Skip to main content

Full text of "Industrial democracy"

See other formats


0^ 


^ 


fr 


u 


s^ 


^    ^ 


INDUSTRIAL     DEMOCRACY 


INDUSTRIAL    DEMOCRACY 
BY  SIDNEY  AND  BEATRICE 

WEBB.       NEW    EDITION    IN     TWO 
VOLUMES    BOUND    IN    ONE. 


LONGMANS,  GREEN  AND  CO.,  39 
PATERNOSTER  ROW,  LONDON, 
NEW  YORK,  AND  BOMBAY.  1902. 


HD 


PREFACE 

WE  have  attempted  in  these  volumes  to  give  a  scientific 
analysis  of  Trade  Unionism  in  the  United  Kingdom.  To 
this  task  we  have  devoted  six  years'  investigation,  in  the 
course  of  which  we  have  examined,  inside  and  out,  the 
constitution  of  practically  every  Trade  Union  organisation, 
together  with  the  methods  and  regulations  which  it  uses  to 
attain  its  ends.  In  the  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  published 
in  1894,  we  traced  the  origin  and  growth  of  the  Trade 
Union  movement  as  a  whole,  industrially  and  politically, 
concluding  with  a  statistical  account  of  the  distribution  of 
Trade  Unionism  according  to  trades  and  localities  ;  and  a 
sketch  from  nature  of  Trade  Union  life  and  character.  The 
student  has,  therefore,  already  had  before  him  a  picture  of 
those  external  characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism,  past  and 
present,  which — borrowing  a  term  from  the  study  of  animal 
life — we  may  call  its  natural  history.  These  external 
characteristics — the  outward  form  and  habit  of  the  creature — 
are  obviously  insufficient  for  any  scientific  generalisation  as  to 
its  purpose  and  its  effects.  Nor  can  any  useful  conclusions, 
theoretic  or  practical,  be  arrived  at  by  arguing  from  "  common 
notions"  about  Trade  Unionism  ;  nor  even  by  refining  these 
into  a  definition  of  some  imaginary  form  of  combination 
in  the  abstract.  Sociology,  like  all  other  sciences,  can  ad- 
vance only  upon  the  basis  of  a  precise  observation  of  actual 
facts. 

The  first  part  of  our  work  deals  with  Trade  Union  Struc- 
ture. In  the  Anglo-Saxon  world  of  to-day  we  find  that  Trade 
Unions  are  democracies  :  that  is  to  say,  their  internal  constitu- 


vi  Industrial  Democracy 

lions  arc  all  based  on  the  principle  of  "  government  of  the 
people  by  the  people  for  the  people."     How  far  they  are 
marked  off  from  political  governments  by  their  membership 
being  voluntary  will  be  dealt  with  in  the  course  of  the  analysis. 
They  are,   however,   scientifically   distinguished   from  other 
democracies  in  that  they  are  composed  exclusively  of  manual- 
working  wage -earners,  associated  according  to  occupations. 
We  shall  show  how  the  different  Trade  Unions  reveal  this 
species  of  democracy  at  many  different  stages  of  development. 
This  part  of  the  book  will  be  of  little  interest  to  those  who 
want  simply  to  know  whether  Trade  Unionism  is  a  good  or 
a   bad  influence   in  the  State.      To  employers   and  Trade 
Union  officials  on  active  service  in  the  campaign  between 
Capital   and  Labor,  or  to  politicians   hesitating  which  side 
to  take  in  a  labor  struggle,  our  detailed  discussions   of  the 
relations  between  elector,  representative,  and  civil  servant ; 
between  central  and  local  government ;  and  between  taxation 
and  representation — not  to  speak  of  the  difficulties  connected 
with  federation,  the  grant  of  "  Home  Rule  "  to  minorities,  or 
the  use  of  the  Referendum  and  the  Initiative — will   seem 
tedious  and  irrelevant.     On  the  other  hand,  the  student  of  de- 
mocracy, not  specially  interested  in  the.  commercial  aspect  of 
Trade  Unionism,  will  probably  find  this  the  most  interesting 
part  of  the  book.     Those  who  regard  the  participation  of  the 
manual-working  wage-earners  in  the  machinery  of  government 
as  the  distinctive,  if  not  the  dangerous,  element  in  modern 
politics,  will  here  find  the  phenomenon  isolated.     These  thou- 
sands of  working-class  democracies,  spontaneously  growing  up 
at  different  times  and  places,  untrammelled  by  the  traditions  or 
interests  of  other  classes,  perpetually  recasting  their  constitu- 
tions to  meet  new  and  varying  conditions,  present  an  unrivalled 
field  of  observation  as  to  the  manner  in  which  the  working 
man   copes  with  the  problem  of  combining   administrative 
efficiency  with  popular  control. 

The  second  part  of  the  book,  forming  more  than  half  its 
total  bulk,  consists  of  a  descriptive  analysis  of  Trade  Union 
Function  :  that  is  to  say,  of  the  methods  used,  the  regulations 


Preface  vii 

imposed,  and  the  policy  followed  by  Trade  Unions.  We 
have  done  our  best  to  make  this  analysis  both  scientifically 
accurate  and,  as  regards  the  United  Kingdom  at  the  present 
day,  completely  exhaustive.  We  have,  of  course,  not  enumer- 
ated every  individual  regulation  of  every  individual  union  ; 
but  we  have  pushed  our  investigations  into  every  trade  in 
every  part  of  the  kingdom  ;  and  our  analysis  includes,  we 
believe,  every  existing  type  and  variety  of  Trade  Union 
action.  And  we  have  sought  to  make  our  description 
quantitative.  We  have  given  statistics  wherever  these  could 
be  obtained  ;  and  we  have,  in  all  cases,  tried  to  form  and 
convey  to  the  reader  an  impression  of  the  relative  proportion, 
statical  and  dynamic,  which  each  type  of  regulation  bears  to 
the  whole  body  of  Trade  Union  activity.  In  digesting  the 
almost  innumerable  technical  regulations  of  every  trade,  our 
first  need  was  a  scientific  classification.  After  many  experi- 
ments we  discovered  the  principle  of  this  to  lie  in  the  psycho- 
logical origin  of  the  several  regulations :  that  is  to  say,  the 
direct  intention  with  which  they  were  adopted,  or  the  im- 
mediate grievance  they  were  designed  to  remedy.  Our 
consequent  observations  threw  light  on  many  apparent  con- 
tradictions and  inconsistencies.  Thus,  to  mention  only  two 
among  many  instances,  the  student  will  find,  in  our  chapter  on 
"  The  Standard  Rate,"  an  explanation  of  the  reason  why  some 
Trade  Unions  strike  against  Piecework  and  others  against 
Timework  ;  and,  in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Normal  Day,"  why 
some  Trade  Unions  make  the  regulation  of  the  hours  of 
labor  one  of  their  foremost  objects,  whilst  others,  equally 
strong  and  aggressive,  are  indifferent,  if  not  hostile  to  it. 
The  same  principle  of  classification  enables  the  student  to 
comprehend  and  place  in  appropriate  categories  the  seem- 
ingly arbitrary  and  meaningless  regulations,  such  as  those 
against  "  Smooting "  or  "  Partnering,"  which  bewilder  the 
superficial  observer  of  working-class  life.  It  assists  us  to 
unravel  the  intricate  changes  of  Trade  Union  policy  with 
regard  to  such  matters  as  machinery,  apprenticeship,  and  the 
admission  of  women.  It  serves  also  for  the  deeper  analysis 


viii  Industrial  Democracy 

of  the  division  of  the  whole  action  of  Trade  Unionism  into 
three  separate  and  sometimes  mutually  exclusive  policies, 
based  on  different  views  of  what  can  economically  be  effected, 
and  what  state  of  society  is  ultimately  desirable.  It  is 
through  the  psychology  of  its  assumptions  that  we  discover 
how  significantly  the  cleavages  of  opinion  and  action  in  the 
Trade  Union  world  correspond  with  those  in  the  larger  world 
outside. 

It  is  only  in  the  third  part  of  our  work — the  last  four 
chapters  of  the  second  volume — that  we  have  ventured  into 
the  domain  of  theory.  We  first  trace  the  remarkable  change 
of  opinion  among  English  economists  as  to  the  effect  of  Trade 
Unionism  on  the  production  and  distribution  of  wealth.  Some 
readers  may  stop  at  this  point,  contented  with  the  authorita- 
tive, though  vague,  deliverances  favorable  to  combination 
among  wage-earners  now  given  by  the  Professors  of  Political 
Economy  in  the  universities  of  the  United  Kingdom.  But 
this  verdict,  based  in  the  main  upon  an  ideal  conception 
of  competition  and  combination,  seems  to  us  unsubstantial. 
We  have,  therefore,  laid  before  the  student  a  new  analysis  of 
the  working  of  competition  in  the  industrial  field — our  vision 
of  the  organisation  and  working  of  the  business  world  as  it 
actually  exists.  It  is  in  this  analysis  of  the  long  series  of 
bargainings,  extending  from  the  private  customer  in  the 
retail  shop,  back  to  the  manual  laborer  in  the  factory  or  the 
mine,  that  we  discover  the  need  for  Trade  Unionism.  We 
then  analyse  the  economic  characteristics,  not  of  combination 
in  the  abstract  in  a  world  of  ideal  competition,  but  of  the 
actual  Trade  Unionism  of  the  present  day  in  the  business, 
world  as  we  know  it.  Here,  therefore,  we  give  our  own 
theory  of  Trade  Unionism — our  own  interpretation  of  the 
way  in  which  the  methods  and  regulations  that  we  have 
described  actually  affect  the  production  and  distribution  of 
wealth  and  the  development  of  personal  character.  This 
theory,  in  conjunction  with  our  particular  view  of  social 
expediency,  leads  us  to  sum  up  emphatically  in  favor 
of  Trade  Unionism  of  one  type,  and  equally  emphatically 


Preface  ix 

against  Trade  Unionism  of  another  type.  In  our  final 
chapter  we  even  venture  upon  precept  and  prophecy  ;  and  we 
consider  the  exact  scope  of  Trade  Unionism  in  the  fully 
developed  democratic  state — the  industrial  democracy  of  the 
future. 

A  book  made  up  of  descriptions  of  fact,  generalisations 
into  theory,  and  moral  judgments  must,  in  the  best  case, 
necessarily  include  parts  of  different  degrees  of  use.  The 
description  of  structure  and  function  in  Parts  I.  and  II.  will, 
we  hope,  have  its  own  permanent  value  in  sociology  as  an 
analytic  record  of  Trade  Unionism  in  a  particular  country  at 
a  particular  date.  The  economic  generalisations  contained 
in  Part  III.,  if  they  prove  sound  on  verification  by  other 
investigators,  can  be  no  more  than  stepping-stones  for  the 
generalisations  of  reasoners  who  will  begin  where  we  leave 
off.  Like  all  scientific  theories,  they  will  be  quickly  broken 
up,  part  to  be  rejected  as  fallacious  or  distorted,  and  part 
to  be  absorbed  in  later  and  larger  views.  Finally,  even 
those  who  regard  our  facts  as  accurate,  and  accept  our 
economic  theory  as  scientific,  will  only  agree  in  our  judg- 
ment of  Trade  Unionism,  and  in  our  conception  of  its 
permanent  but  limited  function  in  the  Industrial  Democracy 
of  the  future,  in  so  far  as  they  happen  to  be  at  one  with  us 
in  the  view  of  what  state  of  society  is  desirable. 


Those  who  contemplate  scientific  work  in  any  depart- 
ment of  Sociology  may  find  some  practical  help  in  a  brief 
account  of  the  methods  of  investigation  which  we  have  found 
useful  in  this  and  other  studies. 

To  begin  with,  the  student  must  resolutely  set  himself 
to  find  out,  not  the  ultimate  answer  to  the  practical 
problem  that  may  have  tempted  him  to  the  work,  but  what 
is  the  actual  structure  and  function  of  the  organisation 
about  which  he  is  interested.  Thus,  his  primary  task  is 
to  observe  and  dissect  facts,  comparing  as  many  specimens 


x  Industrial  Democracy 

as  possible,  and  precisely  recording  all  their  resemblances 
and  differences  whether  or  not  they  seem  significant.  This 
does  not  mean  that  the  scientific  observer  ought  to  start  with 
a  mind  free  from  preconceived  ideas  as  to  classification  and 
sequences.  If  such  a  person  existed,  he  would  be  able  to 
make  no  observations  at  all.  The  student  ought,  on  the 
contrary,  to  cherish  all  the  hypotheses  he  can  lay  his  hands 
on,  however  far-fetched  they  may  seem.  Indeed,  he  must 
be  on  his  guard  against  being  biassed  by  authority.  As  an 
instrument  for  the  discovery  of  new  truth,  the  wildest  sugges- 
tion of  a  crank  or  a  fanatic,  or  the  most  casual  conclusion 
of  the  practical  man  may  well  prove  more  fertile  than  verified 
generalisations  which  have  already  yielded  their  full  fruit. 
Almost  any  preconceived  idea  as  to  the  connection  between 
phenomena  will  help  the  observer,  if  it  is  only  sufficiently 
limited  in  its  scope  and  definite  in  its  expression  to  be  capable 
of  comparison  with  facts.  What  is  dangerous  is  to  have  only  a 
single  hypothesis,  for  this  inevitably  biasses  the  selection  of 
facts  ;  or  nothing  but  far-reaching  theories  as  to  ultimate 
causes  and  general  results,  for  these  cannot  be  tested  by  any 
facts  that  a  single  student  can  unravel. 

From  the  outset,  the  student  must  adopt  a  definite  prin- 
ciple in  his  note -taking.  We  have  found  it  convenient  to  use 
separate  sheets  of  paper,  uniform  in  shape  and  size,  each  of 
which  is  devoted  to  a  single  observation,  with  exact  particulars 
of  authority,  locality,  and  date.  To  these,  as  the  inquiry 
proceeds,  we  add  other  headings  under  which  the  recorded 
fact  might  possibly  be  grouped,  such,  for  instance,  as  the 
industry,  the  particular  section  of  the  craft,  the  organisation, 
the  sex,  age,  or  status  of  the  persons  concerned,  the  psycho- 
logical intention,  or  the  grievance  to  be  remedied.  These 
sheets  can  be  shuffled  and  reshuffled  into  various  orders, 
according  as  it  is  desired  to  consider  the  recorded  facts  in 
their  distribution  in  time  or  space,  or  their  coincidence 
with  other  circumstances.  The  student  would  be  well- 
advised  to  put  a  great  deal  of  work  into  the  completeness 
and  mechanical  perfection  of  his  note-taking,  even  if  this 


Preface  xi 

involves,  for  the  first  few  weeks  of  the  inquiry,  copying  and 
recopying  his  material. 

Before  actually  beginning  the  investigation  it  is  well  to 
read  what  has  been  previously  written  about  the  subject. 
This  will  lead  to  some  tentative  ideas  as  to  how  to  break 
up  the  material  into  definite  parts  for  separate  dissection. 
It  will  serve  also  to  collect  hypotheses  as  to  the  con- 
nections between  the  facts.  It  is  here  that  the  voluminous 
proceedings  of  Royal  Commissions  and  Select  Committees 
find  their  real  use.  Their  innumerable  questions  and 
answers  seldom  end  in  any  theoretic  judgment  or  practical 
conclusion  of  scientific  value.  To  the  investigator,  however, 
they  often  prove  a  mine  of  unintentional  suggestion  and 
hypothesis,  just  because  they  are  collections  of  samples 
without  order  and  often  without  selection. 

In  proceeding  to  actual  investigation  into  facts,  there  are 
three  good  instruments  of  discovery  :  the  Document,  Personal 
Observation,  and  the  Interview.  All  three  are  useful  in 
obtaining  preliminary  suggestions  and  hypotheses  ;  but  as 
methods  of  qualitative  and  quantitative  analysis,  or  of  verifica- 
tion, they  are  altogether  different  in  character  and  unequal 
in  value. 

The  most  indispensable  of  these  instruments  is  the 
Document.  It  is  a  peculiarity  of  human,  and  especially  of 
social  action,  that  it  secretes  records  of  facts,  not  with  any 
view  to  affording  material  for  the  investigator,  but  as  data 
for  the  future  guidance  of  the  organisms  themselves.  The 
essence  of  the  Document  as  distinguished  from  the  mere 
literature  of  the  subject  is  the  unintentional  and  automatic 
character  of  its  testimony.  It  is,  in  short,  a  kind  of 
mechanical  memory,  registering  facts  with  the  minimum  of 
persona]  bias.  Hence  the  cash  accounts,  minutes  of  private 
meetings,  internal  statistics,  rules,  and  reports  of  societies  of 
all  kinds  furnish  invaluable  material  from  which  the  in- 
vestigator discovers  not  only  the  constitution  and  policy  of 
the  organisation,  but  also  many  of  its  motives  and  intentions. 
Even  documents  intended  solely  to  influence  other  people, 


xii  Industrial  Democracy 

such  as  public  manifestoes  or  fictitious  reports,  have  their 
documentary  value  if  only  as  showing  by  comparison  with 
the  confidential  records,  what  it  was  that  their  authors 
desired  to  conceal.  The  investigator  must,  therefore, 
collect  every  document,  however  unimportant,  that  he  can 
acquire.  When  acquisition  is  impossible,  he  should  copy  the 
actual  words,  making  his  extracts  as  copious  as  time  permits  ; 
for  he  can  never  know  what  will  afterwards  prove  significant 
to  him.  In  this  use  of  the  Document,  sociology  possesses  a 
method  of  investigation  which  to  some  extent  compensates 
it  for  inability  to  use  the  method  of  deliberate  experiment. 
We  venture  to  think  that  collections  of  documents  will  be  to 
the  sociologist  of  the  future,  what  collections  of  fossils  or  skele- 
tons are  to  the  zoologist ;  and  libraries  will  be  his  museums. 
Next  in  importance  comes  the  method  of  Personal 
Observation.  By  this  we  mean  neither  the  Interview  nor 
yet  any  examination  of  the  outward  effects  of  an  organisation, 
but  a  continued  watching,  from  inside  the  machine,  of  the 
actual  decisions  of  the  human  agents  concerned,  and  the  play 
of  motives  from  which  these  spring.  The  difficulty  for  the 
investigator  is  to  get  into  such  a  post  of  observation  without 
his  presence  altering  the  normal  course  of  events.  It  is 
here,  and  here  only,  that  personal  participation  in  the  work  of 
any  social  organisation  is  of  advantage  to  scientific  inquiry. 
The  railway  manager,  the  member  of  a  municipality,  or  the 
officer  of  a  Trade  Union  would,  if  he  were  a  trained  investi- 
gator, enjoy  unrivalled  opportunities  for  precisely  describing 
the  real  constitution  and  actual  working  of  his  own  organisa- 
tion. Unfortunately,  it  is  extremely  rare  to  find  in  an  active 
practical  administrator,  either  the  desire,  the  capacity,  or  the 
training  for  successful  investigation.  The  outsider  wishing 
to  use  this  method  is  practically  confined  to  one  of  two 
alternatives.  He  may  adopt  the  social  class,  join  the 
organisation,  or  practise  the  occupation  that  he  wishes  to 
study.  Thus,  one  of  the  authors  has  found  it  useful,  af 
different  stages  of  investigation,  to  become  a  rent  collector, 
a  tailoress,  and  a  working-class  lodger  in  working-class 


Preface  xiii 

families ;  whilst  the  other  has  gained  much  from  active 
membership  of  democratic  organisations  and  personal  par- 
ticipation in  administration  in  more  than  one  department. 
Participation  of  this  active  kind  may  be  supplemented  by 
gaining  the  intimacy  and  confidence  of  persons  and  organisa- 
tions, so  as  to  obtain  the  privilege  of  admission  to  their 
establishments,  offices,  and  private  meetings.  In  this  passive 
observation  the  woman,  we  think,  is  specially  well-adapted 
for  sociological  inquiry  ;  not  merely  because  she  is  accustomed 
silently  to  watch  motives,  but  also  because  she  gains  access  and 
confidence  which  are  instinctively  refused  to  possible  com- 
mercial competitors  or  political  opponents.  The  worst  of 
this  method  of  Personal  Observation  is  that  the  observer  can 
seldom  resist  giving  undue  importance  to  the  particular  facts 
and  connections  between  facts  that  he  happens  to  have  seen. 
He  must,  therefore,  record  what  he  has  observed  as  a  set  of 
separate,  and  not  necessarily  connected  facts,  to  be  used  merely 
as  hypotheses  of  classification  and  sequence,  for  verification  by 
an  exhaustive  scrutiny  of  documents  or  by  the  wider-reaching 
method  of  the  Interview. 

By  the  Interview  as  an  instrument  of  sociological  inquiry 
we  mean  something  more  than  the  preliminary  talks  and 
social  friendliness  which  form,  so  to  speak,  the  antechamber 
to  obtaining  documents  and  opportunities  for  personal 
observation  of  processes.  The  Interview  in  the  scientific 
sense  is  the  skilled  interrogation  of  a  competent  witness  as 
to  facts  within  his  personal  experience.  As  the  witness  is 
under  no  compulsion,  the  interviewer  will  have  to  listen 
sympathetically  to  much  that  is  not  evidence,  namely  to 
personal  opinions,  current  tradition,  and  hearsay  reports  of 
facts,  all  of  which  may  be  useful  in  suggesting  new  sources 
of  inquiry  and  revealing  bias.  But  the  real  business  of  the 
Interview  is  to  ascertain  facts  actually  seen  by  the  person 
interviewed.  Thus,  the  expert  interviewer,  like  the  bedside 
physician,  agrees  straightway  with  all  the  assumptions  and 
generalisations  of  his  patient,  and  uses  his  detective  skill  to 
sift,  by  tactful  cross-examination,  the  grain  of  fact  from  the 


xiv  Industrial  Democracy 

bushel  of  sentiment,  self-interest,  and  theory.  Hence,  though 
it  is  of  the  utmost  importance  to  make  friends  with  the  head 
of  any  organisation,  we  have  generally  got  much  more  actual 
information  from  his  subordinates  who  are  personally  occupied 
with  the  facts  in  detail.  But  in  no  case  can  any  Interview 
be  taken  as  conclusive  evidence,  even  in  matters  of  fact.  It 
must  never  be  forgotten  that  every  man  is  biassed  by  his 
creed  or  his  self-interest,  his  class  or  his  views  of  what  is 
socially  expedient.  If  the  investigator  fails  to  detect  this  bias, 
it  may  be  assumed  that  it  coincides  with  his  own  !  Conse- 
quently, the  fullest  advantage  of  the  Interview  can  be  obtained 
only  at  the  later  stages  of  an  inquiry,  when  the  student  has 
so  far  progressed  in  his  analysis  that  he  knows  exactly  what 
to  ask  for.  It  then  enables  him  to  verify  his  provisional 
conclusions  as  to  the  existence  of  certain  specified  facts,  and 
their  relations  to  others.  And  there  is  a  wider  use  of  the 
Interview  by  which  a  quantitative  value  may  be  given  to  a 
qualitative  analysis.  Once  the  investigator  has  himself 
dissected  a  few  type  specimens,  and  discovered  which  among 
their  obviously  recognisable  attributes  possess  significance  for 
him,  he  may  often  be  able  to  gain  an  exhaustive  knowledge 
of  the  distribution  of  these  attributes  by  what  we  may  call 
the  method  of  wholesale  interviewing.  One  of  the  most 
brilliant  and  successful  applications  of  this  method  was  Mr. 
Charles  Booth's  use  of  all  the  School  Board  visitors  of  the 
East  End  of  London.  Having,  by  personal  observation,  dis- 
covered certain  obvious  marks  which  coincided  with  a  scien- 
tific classification  of  the  East  End  population,  he  was  able, 
by  interviewing  a  few  hundred  people,  to  obtain  definite  par- 
ticulars with  regard  to  the  status  of  a  million.  And  when 
results  so  obtained  are  checked  by  other  investigations — say, 
for  instance,  by  the  Census,  itself  only  a  gigantic  and  some- 
what unscientific  system  of  wholesale  interviewing — a  high 
degree  of  verified  quantitative  value  may  sometimes  be  given 
to  sociological  inquiry. 

Finally,  we  would  suggest  that  it  is  a  peculiar  advantage, 
in  all  sociological  work,  if  a  single  inquiry  can  be  conducted 


Preface  xv 

by  more  than  one  person.  A  closely-knit  group,  dealing 
contemporaneously  with  one  subject,  will  achieve  far  more 
than  the  same  persons  working  individually.  In  our  inquiry 
into  Trade  Unionism  we  have  found  exceptionally  useful,  not 
only  our  own  collaboration  in  all  departments  of  the  work, 
but  also  the  co-operation,  throughout  the  whole  six  years,  of 
our  colleague  and  friend,  Mr.  F.  W.  Galton.  When  the 
members  of  a  group  "  pool "  their  stocks  of  preconceived 
ideas  or  provisional  hypotheses  ;  their  personal  experience  of 
the  facts  in  question,  or  of  analogous  facts ;  their  knowledge 
of  possible  sources  of  information  ;  their  opportunities  for 
interviewing,  and  access  to  documents,  they  are  better  able 
than  any  individual  to  cope  with  the  vastness  and  com- 
plexity of  even  a  limited  subject  of  sociological  investigation. 
They  can  do  much  by  constant  criticism  to  save  each  other 
from  bias,  crudities  of  observation,  mistaken  inferences,  and 
confusion  of  thought.  But  group -work  of  this  kind  has 
difficulties  and  dangers  of  its  own.  Unless  all  the  members 
are  in  intimate  personal  communication  with  each  other, 
moving  with  a  common  will  and  purpose,  and  at  least  so  far 
equal  in  training  and  capacity  that  they  can  understand  each 
other's  distinctions  and  qualifications,  the  result  of  their 
common  labors  will  present  blurred  outlines,  and  be  of  little 
real  value.  Without  unity,  equality,  and  discipline,  different 
members  of  the  group  will  always  be  recording  identical 
facts  under  different  names,  and  using  the  same  term  to 
denote  different  facts. 

By  the  pursuit  of  these  methods  of  observation  and 
verification,  any  intelligent,  hard-working,  and  conscientious 
students,  or  group  of  students,  applying  themselves  to 
definitely  limited  pieces  of  social  organisation,  will  certainly 
produce  monographs  of  scientific  value.  Whether  "they  will 
be  able  to  extract  from  their  facts  a  new  generalisation, 
applicable  to  other  facts — whether,  that  is  to  say,  they  will 
discover  any  new  scientific  law — will  depend  on  the  possession 
of  a  somewhat  rare  combination  of  insight  and  inventiveness, 
with  the  capacity  for  prolonged  and  intense  reasoning.  When 

b 


xvi  Industrial  Democracy 

such  a  generalisation  is  arrived  at,  it  provides  a  new  field  of 
work  for  the  ensuing  generation,  whose  task  it  is,  by  an 
incessant  testing  of  this  "  order  of  thought "  by  comparison 
with  the  "  order  of  things,"  to  extend,  limit,  and  qualify  the 
first  imperfect  statement  of  the  law.  By  these  means  alone, 
whether  in  sociology  or  any  other  sphere  of  human  inquiry, 
does  mankind  enter  into  possession  of  that  body  of  organised 
knowledge  which  is  termed  science. 

We  venture  to  add  a  few  words  as  to  the  practical  value 
of  sociological  investigation.  Quite  apart  from  the  interest 
of  the  man  of  science,  eager  to  satisfy  his  curiosity  about 
every  part  of  the  universe,  a  knowledge  of  social  facts 
and  laws  is  indispensable  for  any  intelligent  and  deliberate 
human  action.  The  whole  of  social  life,  the  entire  structure 
and  functioning  of  society,  consists  of  human  intervention. 
The  essential  characteristic  of  civilised,  as  distinguished  from 
savage  society,  is  that  these  interventions  are  not  impulsive 
but  deliberate  ;  for,  though  some  sort  of  human  society  may 
get  along  upon  instinct,  civilisation  depends  upon  organised 
knowledge  of  sociological  facts  and  of  the  connections  between 
them.  And  this  knowledge  must  be  sufficiently  generalised  to 
be  capable  of  being  diffused.  We  can  all  avoid  being  practical 
engineers  or  chemists ;  but  no  consumer,  producer,  or  citizen 
can  avoid  being  a  practical  sociologist.  Whether  he  pursues 
only  his  own  pecuniary  self-interest,  or  follows  some  idea  of 
class  or  social  expediency,  his  action  or  inaction  will  promote 
his  ends  only  in  so  far  as  it  corresponds  with  the  real  order  of 
the  universe.  A  workman  may  join  his  Trade  Union,  or 
abstain  from  joining  ;  but  if  his  decision  is  to  be  rational, 
it  must  be  based  on  knowledge  of  what  the  Trade  Union  is, 
how  far  it  is  a  sound  benefit  society,  whether  its  methods 
will  increase  or  decrease  his  liberty,  and  to  what  extent  its 
regulations  are  likely  to  improve  or  deteriorate  the  conditions 
of  employment  for  himself  and  his  class.  The  employer  who 
desires  to  enjoy  the  maximum  freedom  of  enterprise,  or  to 
gain  the  utmost  profit,  had  better,  before  either  fighting  his 
workmen  or  yielding  to  their  demands,  find  out  the  cause  and 


Preface  xvii 

meaning  of  Trade  Unionism,  what  exactly  it  is  likely  to  give 
up  or  insist  on,  its  financial  strength  and  weakness,  and  its 
hold  on  public  opinion.  Common  hearsay,  or  the  gossip  of 
a  club,  whether  this  be  the  public-house  or  a  palace  in  Pall 
Mall,  will  no  more  enable  a  man  intelligently  to  "  manage  his 
own  business,"  than  it  will  enable  the  engineer  to  build  a 
bridge.  And  when  we  pass  from  private  actions  to  the  par- 
ticipation of  men  and  women  as  electors,  representatives,  or 
officials,  in  public  companies,  local  governing  bodies,  or  the 
State  itself,  the  inarticulate  apprehension  of  facts  which  often 
contents  the  individual  business  man,  will  no  longer  suffice. 
Deliberate  corporate  action  involves  some  definite  policy, 
communicable  to  others.  The  town  councillor  or  the  cabinet 
minister  has  perpetually  to  be  making  up  his  mind  what  is 
to  be  done  in  particular  cases.  Whether  his  action  or 
abstention  from  action  is  likely  to  be  practicable,  popular, 
and  permanently  successful  in  attaining  his  ends,  depends  on 
whether  it  is  or  is  not  adapted  to  the  facts.  This  does  not 
mean  that  every  workman  and  every  employer,  or  even  every 
philanthropist  and  every  statesman,  is  called  upon  to  make 
his  own  investigation  into  social  questions  any  more  than 
to  make  for  himself  the  physiological  investigations  upon 
which  his  health  depends.  But  whether  they  like  it  or  not, 
their  success  or  failure  to  attain  their  ends  depends  on  their 
scientific  knowledge,  original  or  borrowed,  of  the  facts  of  the 
problem,  and  of  their  causal  connections.  Perfect  wisdom 
we  can  never  attain,  in  sociology  or  in  any  other  science  ; 
but  this  does  not  absolve  us  from  using,  in  our  action,  the 
most  authoritative  exposition,  for  the  time  being,  of  what  is 
known.  That  nation  will  achieve  the  greatest  success  in  the 
world-struggle,  whose  investigators  discover  the  greatest  body 
of  scientific  truth,  and  whose  practical  men  are  the  most 
prompt  in  their  application  of  it. 

What  is  not  generally  recognised  is  that  scientific  investi- 
gation, in  the  field  of  sociology  as  in  other  departments  of 
knowledge,  requires,  not  only  competent  investigators,  but  a 
considerable  expenditure.  Practically  no  provision  exists  in 


xviii  Industrial  Democracy 

this  country  for  the  endowment  or  support  from  public  funds 
of  any  kind  of  sociological  investigation.  It  is,  accordingly, 
impossible  at  present  to  make  any  considerable  progress 
even  with  inquiries  of  pressing  urgency.  Social  reformers  are 
always  feeling  themselves  at  a  standstill,  for  sheer  lack  of 
knowledge,  and  of  that  invention  which  can  only  proceed 
from  knowledge.  There  is,  we  believe,  no  purpose  to  which 
the  rich  man  could  devote  his  surplus  with  greater  utility  to 
the  community  than  the  setting  on  foot,  in  the  hands  of 
competent  investigators,  of  definite  inquiries  into  such 
questions  as  the  administrative  control  of  the  liquor  traffic, 
the  relation  between  local  and  central  government,  the  popu- 
lation question,  the  conditions  of  women's  industrial  employ- 
ment, the  real  incidence  of  taxation,  the  working  of  municipal 
administration,  or  many  other  unsolved  problems  that  could 
be  named.  It  may  be  assumed  that  to  deal  adequately 
with  any  of  these  subjects  would  involve  an  out-of-pocket 
expenditure  for  travelling,  materials,  and  incidental  outlays 
of  all  kinds,  of  something  like  ;£iooo,  irrespective  of  the 
maintenance  of  the  investigators  themselves,  or  the  possible 
expense  of  publication.  To  make  any  permanent  provision 
for  discovery  in  any  one  department — to  endow  a  chair — 
requires  the  investment  of,  say,  ;£  10,000.  At  present,  in 
London,  the  wealthiest  city  in  the  world,  and  the  best  of  all 
fields  for  sociological  investigation,  the  sum  total  of  the 
endowments  for  this  purpose  does  not  reach  ;£ioo  a  year. 

It  remains  only  to  express  our  grateful  acknowledgments 
to  the  many  friends,  employers  as  well  as  workmen,  who  have 
helped  us  with  information  as  to  their  respective  trades. 
Some  portions  of  our  work  have  been  read  in  manuscript  or 
proof  by  Professor  Edgeworth,  Professor  Hewins,  Mr.  Leonard 
Hobhouse,  and  other  friends,  to  whom  we  are  indebted  for 
many  useful  suggestions  and  criticisms.  Early  drafts  of 
some  chapters  have  appeared  in  the  Economic  Journal, 
Economic  Review,  Nineteenth  Century,  and  Progressive  Revieiv 
in  this  country  ;  the  Political  Science  Quarterly  in  New  York  ; 


Preface  xix 

and  Dr.  Braun's  Archiv  fur  Sociale  Gesetzgebung  und  Statistik 
in  Berlin.  They  are  reproduced  here  by  permission  of  the 
editors.  A  large  portion  of  the  book  was  given  in  the  form 
of  lectures  at  the  London  School  of  Economics  and  Political 
Science  during  1896  and  1897. 

SIDNEY  AND  BEATRICE  WEBB. 


41  GROSVENOR  ROAD,  WESTMINSTER, 
LONDON,  November  1897. 


INTRODUCTION   TO   THE    1902 
EDITION 

(FOURTH  IMPRESSION.     FIFTH  THOUSAND.) 

THE  issue  of  Industrial  Democracy  in  a  cheaper  edition, 
uniform  with  the  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  gives  us  an 
opportunity  of  writing  a  new  introductory  chapter. 

We  have  practically  nothing  to  add  to  the  descriptive 
and  analytic  part  of  the  book.  During  the  four  years  which 
have  elapsed  since  its  publication,  the  Trade  Union  world 
has  not  appreciably  changed  in  structure  or  function.1  The 
Trade  Union  "  methods "  of  Mutual  Insurance,  Collective 
Bargaining,  and  Legal  Enactment — the  multifarious  Trade 
Union  "  regulations "  described  in  our  chapters  on  the 
Standard  Rate  and  the  Normal  Day,  New  Processes  and 
Machinery,  and  the  Entrance  to  a  Trade — retain  their 
several  places  in  the  workmen's  constant  struggle  to  uphold 
and  improve  the  Standard  of  Life  of  their  class.  But  whilst 
the  Trade  Union  world  itself  has  remained  unaltered,  the 
closing  years  of  the  nineteenth  century  have  witnessed  a 
gradual  change  in  Trade  Union  environment,  alike  in  law 
and  in  public  opinion,  which  has  lately  risen,  suddenly  and 
dramatically,  into  public  consciousness.  By  a  series  of 
remarkable  legal  decisions  of  the  House  of  Lords,  the  Trade 
Unions  of  the  United  Kingdom  have  seen  their  use  of  the 

1  Trade  Union  membership  and  Trade  Union  funds  have,  indeed,  greatly 
increased,  until,  at  the  present  time,  there  are  not  far  short  of  two  million 
members,  with  accumulated  funds  of  nearly  four  millions  sterling.  But  these 
statistical  details,  including  some  analysis  of  the  direction  of  growth,  we  reserve 
for  the  forthcoming  edition  of  the  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  in  which  we  deal 
also  with  the  principal  strikes  of  the  last  decade. 


xxii  Industrial  Democracy 

Method  of  Collective  Bargaining  seriously  curtailed.  At 
the  same  time,  an  equally  remarkable  series  of  legislative 
experiments  in  the  Britains  beyond  the  sea  have  made 
possible  applications  of  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment 
hitherto  undreamt  of. 

We  must  first  refer,  in  order  to  bring  our  analysis  up  to 
date,  to  a  few  statutory  changes  in  the  United  Kingdom 
between  1897  and  1902.  The  minimum  age  at  which 
children  may  be  employed  in  factories  or  workshops  (pp. 
768-69)  is  now  twelve,  and  in  mines,  thirteen  ;  but  practically 
nothing  has  been  done  to  prevent  other  industrial  work  by 
children  of  school  age,1  and  we  are  still  very  far  from  any 
effective  enforcement  of  the  National  Minimum  of  Educa- 
tion which  our  Legislature  professes  to  have  adopted.  The 
serious  evil  of  "  boy  labor  "  (pp.  482-89,  768-71)  has  not  been 
grappled  with.  The  long  array  of  Acts  and  Amending  Acts 
dealing  with  the  conditions  of  employment  in  factories  and 
workshops  (pp.  771-73)  have  now  been  consolidated  in  the 
Factory  and  Workshops  Act  of  1901,  which  includes  a  few 
amendments  of  detail.  But  the  law  still  fails  to  secure, 
even  to  women  and  children,  that  National  Minimum  of 
Sanitation  and  Rest  which  it  purports  to  give.  Whole 
classes  of  women  workers  (p.  772)  remain  excluded  by 
pedantries  of  definition.  The  numerous  exceptions  as 
to  overtime  and  other  relaxations  still  hamper  administra- 
tion (pp.  349-51).  The  sections  dealing  with  laundries 
(P-  365),  outworkers  (p.  772),  and  unhealthy  trades  (pp. 
363-64)  continue,  in  the  main,  illusory  and  inoperative. 
We  may  refer,  on  this  whole  subject,  to  The  Case  for  the 
Factory  Acts  (London,  1901),  edited  by  Mrs.  Sidney 
Webb.  The  objectionable  Truck  Act  of  1896  (pp.  211, 
373»  799)  has  not  been  amended,  but  it  is  right  to  say 
that  it  has  been  found,  in  practice,  much  less  irksome  to 
employers  or  workmen  than  they  severally  expected.  This 
is  due  to  the  fact  that  it  has  been  only  slightly  operative. 

1  See  the  Report  of  the  Departmental  Committee  on  the  Employment  of  Chil- 
dren of  School  Age,  1 90 1 . 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  xxiii 

The  grievances  with  which  the  workmen  hoped  that  it 
would  deal  (pp.  315-18,  840)  have  still  to  be  remedied.1 
The  Workmen's  Compensation  Act  of  1897  (pp.  387- 
91)  has  now  been  extended  to  persons  employed  in 
a^nculliire^but  not  yet  to  workshop  operatives,  seamen, 
carmen,  or  building  workrjieja--engajred  J3n_jbuiljdjngs  less 
than  thirty  feet  in  height.  The  employers  (or,  rather,  the 
insurance  companies  in  their  names)  have  displayed  a  most 
fertile  ingenuity  in  raising  quibbles  intended  to  limit  the 
application  of  the  law,  but  the  highest  judicial  tribunal  has, 
on  the  whole,  given  full  effect  to  the  intention  of  Parliament, 
and  has  made  a  badly-drafted  statute  really  operative.  It 
should  be  added  that  the  actual  cost  of  compensating  for 
accidents  has  proved  less  than  was  anticipated — unfortu- 
nately, as  we  suggested  (pp.  375-76),  much  less  than  it  would 
cost  the  employers  to  prevent  them.  It  remains,  therefore, 
more  important  than  ever,  not  only  to  extend  the  Act  to 
the  workers  at  present  outside  its  scope,  but  also,  in  the 
interest  of  the  community  as  a  whole,  to  enforce  in  all 
occupations  an  effective  National  Minimum  of  Sanitation 
and  Safety  (pp.  375-78,  385-87,  771-73)- 

But  the  changes  in  the  law  effected  by  Parliament 
during  the  past  four  years  are  of  less  importance  to  Trade 
Unionism  than  those  made  by  the  judges,  notably  by  the 
House  of  Lords  in  its  judicial  capacity.  By  a  series  of 
unexpected  decisions,  beginning  with  Allen  v.  Flood,  on  the 
1 4th  of  December  1897,  and  ending,  for  the  moment,  with 
Quinn  v.  Leathern,  on  the  $th  of  August  1901,  the  highest 
court  of  appeal  has  entirely  changed  the  legal  position  of 
Trade  Unions.  We  have,  therefore,  to  consider  in  what 
way  these  decisions  affect  the  conclusions  expressed  in  our 
Appendix  on  "  The  Legal  Position  of  Collective  Bargaining  " 
(pp.  8S3-62).2 

1  We  may  correct  an  error  in  the  note  to  p.  211.      The  Act  proved  not  to 
apply  to  the  deductions  referred  to,  and  no  exemption  order  was  necessary. 

2  The  principal  judgments  in  these  cases  have  been  reprinted  in  The  Law  and 
Trade  Unions  :  a  Brief  Review  of  Recent  Litigation  specially  prepared  at  the  in- 
stance of  Richard  Bell,  M.P.  (London,  1901).     But  the  law  on  the  whole  subject 


xxiv  Industrial  Democracy 

The  most  far-reaching  of  these  decisions,  and  the  one") 
which  gives  importance  to  all  the  others,  is  that  in  the  case( 
of  The  Taff  Vale  Railway  Company  v.  The  Amalgamated  I 
Society  of  Railway  Servants.  There  had  been  a  disput/ 
between  the  railway  company  and  many  of  its  employees. 
A  strike  took  place,  which  was  sanctioned  by  the  governing 
body  of  the  Trade  Union,  and  was  conducted  by  its 
authorised  officers.  It  was  alleged  that,  in  furtherance  of 
this  strike,  some  of  the  agents  of  the  Trade  Union  had 
committed  unlawful  acts,  and  incited  others  to  commit 
them,  to  the  injury  and  damage  of  the  railway  company. 
Instead  of  prosecuting  in  a  criminal  court  the  persons 
alleged  to  have  been  guilty  of  these  offences,  the  company 
applied  to  the  Chancery  Division  of  the  High  Court  of 
Justice  for  an  injunction  to  restrain  from  committing  such 
acts,  not  only  certain  of  the  persons  implicated,  but  also  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Railway  Servants  itself.  The 
company  also  commenced  a  civil  suit  against  the  society  in 
its  corporate  capacity,  claiming  a  large  sum  as  damages  for 
what  were  alleged  to  be  its  wrongful  acts.  The  society 
pleaded  that,  whatever  might  be  the  personal  liability  of 
individual  officers  or  members,  the  Trade  Union  itself  could 
not,  in  its  corporate  capacity,  be  made  the  object  of  an 
injunction,  or  be  sued  for  damages.  It  was  contended  that, 
under  the  circumstances  described  in  our  History  of  Trade 
Unionism,  the  Legislature  had  deliberately  abstained  from 
giving  Trade  Unions  the  privileges  of  incorporation,  and 
had  expressly  provided  against  their  being  sued  as  corporate 
bodies.  This  view  had  been  universally  accepted  by  friends 
and  foes  alike.  The  immunity  of  Trade  Unions  from 
corporate  liability  for  damages  had  been  repeatedly  made 
the  subject  of  official  comment,  and  even  of  recommendations 
by  Royal  Commissions.  For  twenty  years  after  the  Act 

is  now  most  conveniently  to  be  found  in  the  little  volume  of  annotated  statutes 
and  cases,  of  which  we  have  made  use,  entitled  Trade  Union  Law,  by 
Herman  Cohen  and  George  Howell  (London,  1901).  This  gives  exact 
references  to  the  official  reports. 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  xxv 

of  1871  no  action  against  a  Trade  Union  in  its  corporate 
capacity  was  ever  maintained  in  the  English  Courts.1  But 
on  the  22nd  of  July  1901,  the  House  of  Lords  decided  that 
the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Railway  Servants,  though 
admittedly  not  a  corporate  body,  could  be  sued  in  a 
corporate  capacity  for  damages  alleged  to  have  been  caused 
by  the  action  of  its  officers,  and  that  an  injunction  could  be 
issued  against  it,  restraining  it  not  merely  from  criminal, 
but  also  from  other  unlawful  acts.  Moreover,  in  their 
elaborate  reasons  for  their  judgment,  the  law  lords  expressed 
the  view  that  not  only  an  injunction,  but  also  a  mandamus 
could  be  issued  against  a  Trade  Union  ;  that  a  registered 
Trade  Union  could  be  sued  in  its  registered  name ;  that 
even  an  unregistered  Trade  Union  might  be  made  collect- 
ively liable  for  damages,  and  might  be  sued  in  the  names 
of  its  proper  officers,  the  members  of  its  executive  committee, 
and  its  trustees ;  that  the  corporate  funds  of  a  Trade 
Union  could  be  made  answerable  for  costs  and  damages, 
even  if  they  were  in  the  hands  of  trustees  ;  and  that  the 
trustees  of  Trade  Union  funds  might  be  joined  as  parties 
to  a  suit  against  the  Trade  Union,  or  might  be  separately 
proceeded  against  for  recovery  of  damages  and  costs 
awarded  against  their  Trade  Union,  whether  registered 
not.  The  effect  of  the  judgment,  in  short,  is  to  impose 
upon  a  Trade  Union,  whether  registered  or  not — although 
not  incorporated  for  other  purposes — complete  corporate 
liability  for  any  injury  or  damage  caused  by  any  person 
who  can  be  deemed  to  be  acting  as  the  agent  of  the  Trade 
Union,  not  merely  in  respect  of  any  criminal  offence  which 
he  may  have  committed,  but  also  in  respect  of  any  act,  not 
contravening  the  criminal  law,  which  the  judges  may,  froi 
time  to  time,  deem  wrongful. 

1  In  1892,  and  again  in  1895,  civil  proceedings  were  successfully  taken 
by  employers  against  combinations  of  workmen  ;  see  Trollope  and  Others  v. 
The  London  Building  Trades'  Federation  and  Others,  1892  (mentioned  at  p. 
86 1),  and  Pink  v.  The  Federation  of  Trade  Unions,  etc.,  1895.  These 
cases  were,  however,  not  seriously  defended,  not  fully  argued,  and  not  carried 
to  the  highest  tribunal. 


xxvi  Industrial  Democracy 

We  do  not  propose  to  waste  time  in  discussing  whether 
this  judgment  of  the  House  of  Lords  was  or  was  not  in 
accordance  with  the  law  of  the  land  on  the  morning  of  the 
decision.  There  has  seldom  been  an  instance  in  which  a 
judicial  decision  has  so  completely  and  extensively  reversed 
the  previous  legal  opinions,  and — we  do  not  hesitate  to  say 
—the  conscious  intention,  thirty  years  before,  of  Parliament 
itself.  But  the  case  was  fully  and  ably  argued,  and  the 
decision  of  the  five  law  lords  was  unanimous.  According 
to  the  British  Constitution,  the  view  which  they  have  taken 
of  the  law  is  now  as  definitely  the  law  as  if  it  had  been 
embodied  in  an  Act  of  Parliament.  How  does  it  affect 
Trade  Unionism  ? 

At  first  sight  there  would  seem  little  or  nothing  to 
complain  about.  The  judgment  professes  to  make  no 
change  in  the  lawfulness  of  Trade  Unionism.  No  act  is 
ostensibly  made  wrongful  which  was  not  wrongful  before. 
And  if  a  Trade  Union,  directly  or  by  its  agents,  causes 
injury  or  damage  to  other  persons,  by  acts  not  warranted  in 
law,  it  seems  not  inequitable  that  the  Trade  Union  itself 
should  be  made  liable  for  what  it  has  done.  The  real 
grievance  of  the  Trade  Unions,  and  the  serious  danger  to 
their  continued  usefulness  and  improvement,  lies  in  the  un- 
certainty of  the  English  law,  and  its  liability  to  be  used  as  a 
means  of  oppression.  This  danger  is  increased,  and  the 
grievance  aggravated,  by  the  dislike  of  Trade  Unionism  and 
strikes  which  nearly  all  judges  and  juries  share  with  the  rest 
of  the  upper  and  middle  classes. 

The  public  opinion  of  the  propertied  and  professional 
classes  is,  in  fact,  even  more  hostile  to  Trade  Unionism  and 
strikes  than  it  was  a  generation  ago.  In  1867-75,  when 
Trade  Unionism  was  struggling  for  legal  recognition,  it 
seemed  to  many  people  only  fair  that,  as  the  employers 
were  left  free  to  use  their  superiority  in  economic  strength,  the 
workmen  should  be  put  in  a  position  to  make  a  good  fight 
of  it  against  the  employers.  Accordingly,  combinations  and 
strikes  were  legalised,  and  some  sort  of  peaceful  picketing 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  xxvii 

was  expressly  authorised  by  statute.  So  long  as  no  physical 
violence  was  used  or  openly  threatened,  the  mild  tumult 
and  disorder  of  a  strike,  a  certain  amount  of  harmless 
obstruction  of  the  thoroughfares,  and  the  animated  persuasion 
of  blacklegs  by  the  pickets,  were  usually  tolerated  by  the 
police,  and  not  seriously  resented  by  the  employers.  Jjt-alJ- 
belonged  to  the  conception  of  a  labor  dispute  as  a  stand-up 
Eween  the  parties,  in  which  "~tEe~ State'  could  do  no 
more  than  keep  the  ring.  Gradually  this  conception  has 
given  way  in  favour  of  the  view  that,  quite  apart  from  the 
merits  of  the  case}  the  stoppage  of  work  by  an  industrial 
dispute  is  a  public  nuisance,  an  injury  to  the  commonweal, 
which  ought  to  be  prevented  by  the  Government.  More- 
over, the  conditions  of  the  wage  contract  are  no  longer 
regarded  only  as  a  matter  of  private  concern.  The  gradual 
extension  of  legislative  regulation  to  all  industries,  and  its 
successive  application  to  different  classes  of  workers  and 
conditions  of  employment,  decisively  negatives  the  old 
assumption  of  the  employer  that  he  is  entitled  to  hire  his 
labor  on  such  terms  as  he  thinks  fit.  On  the  other  hand, 
public  opinion  has  become  uneasy  about  the  capacity  of 
English  manufacturers  to  hold  their  own  against  foreign 
^colfipetition,  and  therefore  resents,  as  a  crime  against  the 
community,  any  attempt  to  restrict  output  or  obstruct 
machinery,  of  which  the  Trade  Unions  may  be  accused. 
And  thus  we  have  a  growing  public  opinion  in  favour  of 
some  authoritative  tribunal  of  conciliation  or  arbitration,  and 
an  intense  dislike  of  any  organised  interruption  of  industry 
by  a  lock-out  or~  strike,  especial ly^wherr-this^ is  promoted  by 
a  Trade  Union  which  is  believed — often  on  the  strength  of 
the  wildest  accusations  in  the  newspapers — to  be  unfriendly 
to  the  utmost  possible  improvement  of  processes  in  its  trade. 
Under  the  influence  of  this  adverse  bias  the  courts  of 
law  have,  for  the  last  ten  years,  been  gradually  limiting 
what  were  supposed  to  be  the  legal  rights  of  Trade  Unions. 
There  has  been,  it  is  true,  no  attempt  to  bring  back  the 
terrors  of  the  criminal  law,  the  use  of  which,  as  an  instru- 


xxx  Industrial  Democracy 

the  official's  incitement,  some  of  the  workmen  strike  without 
notice,  or  otherwise  break  their  contracts  of  service,  even 
though  the  Trade  Union  official  did  not  intend  that  they 
should  do  so.  And  if  the  judges  should  eventually  hold 
that  any  particular  strike  was  not  warranted,  or,  though 
warranted  in  itself,  that  wrongful  (though  not  criminal)  acts 
were  committed  in  pursuance  of  it,  which  he  might  have 
been  expected  to  foresee,  the  Trade  Union  official  who 
ordered  the  strike  might  very  likely  be  made  answerable  in 
damages  for  the  loss  suffered  by  any  person  through  the 
wrongful  acts  which  he  had  indirectly  but  unwillingly 
caused.  In  all  these  cases,  wherever  a  Trade  Union  official 
would  be  liable,  the  Trade  Union  itself  is  now  made 
collectively  liable.  And  it  follows  from  the  general  law  of 
principal  and  agent,  that  whenever  any  officer  of  a  Trade 
Union,  in  the  ordinary  course  of  his  business,  and  within 
the  apparent  scope  of  his  employment,  does  anything  for 
which  he  is  liable  to  be  sued  for  damages,  the  Trade  Union 
for  which  he  is  acting  becomes  also  liable,  though  he  may 
have  acted  without  orders,  or  contrary  to  the  general  policy 
of  his  Trade  Union,  or  even  in  direct  contradiction  to  the 
private  instructions  which  he  had  received  from  its  executive 
committee.  Finally,  whenever  the  Trade  Union  is  liable  to 
be  sued,  it  will  be  open  to  the  aggrieved  person  to  apply 
to  the  Chancery  Division  of  the  High  Court  of  Justice  for 
an  injunction  against  the  Trade  Union  and  its  officials, 
peremptorily  restraining  them  from  committing  any  of  the 
acts  complained  of.  The  issue  of  such  an  injunction  will 
be  within  the  discretion  of  a  single  Chancery  judge,  and  if 
it  is  disobeyed,  it  can  be  enforced  by  summary  imprison- 
ment, without  trial,  for  an  indefinite  period,  for  what  is 
called  "  contempt  of  court." 

Such  we  believe  to  be  now  the  law,  according  to  the 
best  opinion  that  a  well-informed  counsel  could  give  to  his 
client.  But  so  vague  and  ill-defined,  so  complicated  and 
uncertain,  is  the  English  law  on  such  subjects  as  conspiracy 
and  libel — indeed,  the  whole  law  of  torts — to  say  nothing 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  xxxi 

of  that  relating  to  principal  and  agent,  that  we  cannot 
pretend  that  our  statement  is  to  be  depended  on.  The 
very  uncertainty  is  in  itself  a  serious  grievance.  If  a 
Trade  Union  executive  could  know  precisely  what  was  the 
law,  it  could  take  care  not  to  infringe  it,  and  might  have 
some  chance  of  compelling  its  officers  to  keep  within  their 
legal  rights.  This  is  now  impossible.  All  that  a  Trade 
Union  can  be  sure  of  is  that,  whenever  the  action  of  any 
one  of  its  officers  causes  any  injury^  or  loss  to  ati^-etrrpToyer, 
or  to  any  workman  outside  its  ranks,  it  will  be  open  to  any 
such  person,  at  slight  expense,  to  commence  an  action 
against  the  Trade  Union  for  damages.  This  will  mean,  at 
least,  a  solicitor's  bill.  If  the  action  comes  into  court  the 
Trade  Union  will  know  that,  though  the  jury  may  give  a 
verdict  as  to  the  bare  facts,  the  judgment  will,  in  nine  cases 
out  of  ten,  depend  practically  on  the  judge's  view  of  the 
law.  And  though  we  all  thoroughly  believe  in  the  honesty 
and  impartiality  of  our  judges,  it  so  happens  that,  in  the 
present  uncertainty,  the  very  law  of  the  case  must  necessarily 
turn  on  the  view  taken  of  the  general  policy  of  Trade 
Unionism.  If  the  judges  believed,  as  we  believe,  that 
the  enforcement  of  Common  Rules  in  industry,  and  the 
maintenance  of  a  Standard  Rate,  a  Normal  Day,  and 
stringent  conditions  of  Sanitation  and  Safety,  were  positively 
beneficial  to  the  community  as  a  whole,  and  absolutely 
indispensable  to  the  continued  prosperity  of  our  trade,  they 
would  no  more  hold  liable,  for  any  damage  v/hich,  in  the 
conduct  of  its  legitimate  purpose,  it  incidentally  caused  to 
particular  individuals,  a  reasonably  managed  Trade  Union 
than  a  militant  Temperance  Society  or  the  Primrose  League. 
But  a  clear  majority  of  our  judges  evidently  believe,  quite 
honestly,  that  Trade  Unionism — meaning  the  enforcement 
of  Common  Rules  on  a  whole  trade — is  anomalous,  objec- 
tionable, detrimental  to  English  industry,  and  even  a  wicked 
infringement  of  individual  liberty,  which  Parliament  has 
been  foolishly  persuaded  to  take  out  of  the  category  of 
crimes.  Their  lack  of  economic  training  and  their  ignorance 

c 


XXX11 


Industrial  Democracy 


of  economic  science  is  responsible  for  this  state  of  mind. 
Unfortunately,  their  preoccupation  with  the  technical  side 
of  their  own  profession  renders  it  unlikely  that  they  will 
dispel  this  ignorance  by  any  careful  study  of  labor 
problems.  When,  therefore,  they  have  to  decide  whether 
a  particular  injury,  caused  by  the  operations  of  such  a 
combination,  is  or  is  not  actionable,  they  would  not  be  doing 
their  duty,  holding  the  view  that  they  do  of  its  harmfulness, 
if  they  did  not  treat  it  much  more  severely  than  they  would 
if  precisely  similar  acts  were  committed  by  associations  which 
they  thought  to  be  beneficial  to  the  community — say,  for 
instance,  by  a  combination  of  capitalist  employers,  in  the 
course  of  the  fierce  and  unrelenting  competition  of  inter- 
national trade.  The  result  is  that  Trade  Unions  must  expect 
to  find  practically  every  incident  of  a  strike,  and  possibly 
every  refusal  to  work  with  non-unionists,  treated  as  action- 
able, and  made  the  subject  of  suits  for  damages,  which  the 
Trade  Union  will  have  to  pay  from  its  corporate  funds. 

We  do  not  mean  to  suggest  that  every  little  labor 
trouble  is  likely  to  be  followed  by  a  crop  of  actions  against 
the  Trade  Union  concerned.  Employers  generally  find  it 
too  convenient  to  be  on  good  terms  with  well-managed 
Trade  Unions  to  wish  to  break  off  friendly  negotiations 
with  them.  But  it  will  always  be  open  for  employers  or 
non-unionist  workmen  to  issue  a  writ,  and  in  cases  of  serious 
dispute  it  is  scarcely  likely  that  they  will  all  forego  so  easy 
a  means  of  harassing  their  opponents.  Trade  Unions  will 
not  all  of  them  find  their  funds  denuded  by  heavy  law  costs 
and  damages.  It  may  even  be  some  time  before  a  serious 
case  occurs.  But  the  liability  will  be  always  present.  It 
is  not  too  much  to  say  that,  except  in  the  most  compact 
and  well-disciplined  industries,  a  Union  will,  so  far  as  its 
finances  are  concerned,  when  fighting  is  necessary,  henceforth 
have  to  fight  with  a  halter  round  its  neck.1 

1  No  mere  pious  declarations  in  the  rules  will  protect  a  Trade  Union  from 
actions  for  damages,  if  wrongful  acts  are  done  by  the  Trade  Union  itself  or  by 
iis  agents  acting  within  the  apparent  scope  of  their  authority.  The  judges  will 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  xxxiii 

Ought  the  law  to  be  amended  ?  We  say,  at  once,  that 
Trade  Unions  would,  in  our  opinion,  not  be  warranted  in 
claiming  to  have  restored  that  complete  immunity  from 
legal  proceedings  which  Parliament  intended  to  confer  upon 
them  in  1871-76.  We  see  no  valid  reason  why,  if  the  law 
were  put  into  a  proper  state.  Trade  Unions  should  not  be 
liable  to  be  sued  for  damages  in  their  corporate  capacity,  in 
respect  of  any  injury  wrongfully  done  by  them  or  their 
agents  to  other  persons.  If,  for  instance,  a  Trade  Union 
in  its  corporate  capacity  publishes  a  newspaper,  it  can 
hardly  claim,  as  regards  actions  for  libel,  to  be  treated 
differently  from  any  individual  publisher  of  a  newspaper. 
Nor  can  we  see  any  justification  for  such  an  amendment  of 
the  Conspiracy  and  Law  of  Property  Act,  1875,  as  would 
make  lawful  the  only  sort  of  picketing  likely  to  be  effective 
in  keeping  off  blacklegs  during  a  strike.  Moreover,  if  a 
Trade  Union  violates  its  own  rules,  or  does  anything  plainly 
outside  their  scope,  there  seems  no  ground  for  preventing 
any  dissatisfied  member  from  restraining  its  action  by  an 
injunction.1  Finally,  if  a  Trade  Union  or  its  official 
deliberately  persuades  or  induces  men  to  break  legally 
binding  existing  contracts  of  service  into  which  they  have 
entered,  the  Trade  Union  deserves  to  pay  damages.  So 
far  the  recent  interpretation  of  the  law  must,  we  think,  be 
accepted.  But  Trade  Unions  have  certainly  a  good  claim 
to  have  their  legal  rights  and  liabilities  clearly  defined,  and 
precisely  and  authoritatively  set  forth.  At  present  the  law 
is  merely  a  trap  in  which  any  one  of  them  may  at  any 
moment  be  caught.  We  may  go  further.  So  long  as  the 
community  decides  to  let  the  conditions  of  the  wage-contract 
be  settled  by  bargaining,  both  parties  must,  in  common 
fairness,  be  left  equally  free  to  protect  their  own  interest  by 
combined  action,  even  if  such  combined  action  causes 
damage  to  the  opponent  or  to  others.  It  is  a  mockery  of 

go  behind  the  rules,  if  necessary,  and  form  their  own  conclusion  as  to  the  real  in- 
tentions, purposes,  and  instructions  of  the  executive  committee  or  general  secretary. 
1  Amalgamated  Society  of  Railway  Servants  for  Scotland  v.  The  Motherwell 
Branch  of  the  Society. 


xxxiv  Industrial  Democracy 

justice  to  fell  the  workmen  that  they  are  allowed  to  com- 
bine, and  to  strike,  in  order  to  exact  better  terms  from  their 
employers,  and  then  to  cast  them  in  damages  whenever 
they,  in  the  exercise  of  this  right,  and  without  infringing 
the  criminal  law,  cause  damage  to  other  persons.  Every 
strike,  like  every  other  kind  of  war,  necessarily  causes 
damage  to  other  persons — damage  which  the  strikers  can 
clearly  foresee,  and  which  the  Legislature  must  as  clearly 
have  foreseen  when  it  sanctioned  the  terms  of  labor  being 
left  to  this  kind  of  private  war.1  Moreover,  every  strike — 
as  public  opinion  now  keenly  feels — causes  injury  to  the 
community  as  a  whole.2  This  may  well  be  a  reason  for 
superseding  strikes  as  a  method  of  settling  the  terms  of 
the  contract  of  service.  But  it  is  not  fair  to  the  workmen 
to  try  indirectly  to  put  down  strikes  by  making  the  Trade 
Unions  liable  for  damages  for  what  is  incidental  to  a  strike. 
It  is  handing  them  over  to  the  employers  with  their  hands 
tied.  Trade  Unions  have,  therefore,  a  good  claim  for  an 
alteration  of  the  law.3 

1  "The  third  section  of  [the  Conspiracy  and   Protection  of  Property]  Act 
distinctly   legalises   strikes   in   the   broadest    terms,   subject    to    the    exceptions 
enumerated  in  the  fourth  and  fifth  sections." — Lord  Chief-Justice  Coleridge  in 
Gibson  v.  Lawson  (1891). 

2  Here  lurks  a  danger  to   the  Trade   Unions  of  a  revival  of  the  old  use 
of  the  criminal  law  against  them.     It  is  by  no  means  clear  that  a  conspiracy, 
neither  contemplating  nor  committing  any  criminal  act,  but  violating  an  actionable 
private  right,  may  not  in  itself  be  a  criminal  offence,  if  the  actionable  private 
right  is  one  in  which  the  public  has  a  sufficient  interest.      See  p.  857. 

3  It  may  be  of  service  if  we  submit  in  precise  form  the  draft  of  such  a  bill 
as  Trade  Unionists  might  properly  press  upon  the  Cabinet,  members  of  Parlia- 
ment, and  candidates  for  that  position. 

A  BILL  ENTITLED  AN  ACT  TO  AMEND  THE  LAW  RELATING  TO 
TRADE  DISPUTES 

1.  No  agreement,  combination,  or  conspiracy  entered  into  by  or  on  behalf 
of  an  association  of  employers  or  a  Trade  Union  in  contemplation  or  furtherance 

if  a  trade  dispute,  and  no  act  committed  in  pursuance  of  any  such  agreement, 
combination,  or  conspiracy,  shall  be  actionable,  if  such  act  would  not  be  action- 
able if  committed  by  one  person  without  agreement,  combination,  or  conspiracy 

1  any  kind,  and  if  such  agreement,  combination,  or  conspiracy  would  not  be 
indictable  as  a  crime. 

2.  No  act  committed,  and  no  agreement,  combination,  or  conspiracy  entered 
into,  by  or  on  behalf  of  an  association  of  employers  or  a  Trade  Union  in  con- 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  xxxv 

However  unlikely  it  may  seem  that  our  present  Parlia- 
ment would  consent  to  effect  such  an  alteration  of  the  law 
as  the  Trade  Unionists  desire,  we  venture  to  point  out  that 
the  existing  position  is  not  one  that  can  endure.  The  two 
millions  of  Trade  Unionists,  comprising  probably  one-fifth 
of  the  nationat'eTectoraTe, Twill  certainly  not  consent  to  give 
up  the  enforcement  of  Common  Rules  determining  standard 
minimum  wages  and  other  conditions  throughout  each  trade. 
In  this  policy  they  will  be  supported  by  all  working-class 
opinion,  and  will  be  acting  in  accordance  with  the  teachings 
of  economic  science.1  The  alternative  of  free  and  unfettered 
Individual  Bargaining — in  which  each  workshop  has  its  own 
peculiar  working  hours,  its  own  standard  of  sanitation,  and 
its  own  arrangements  for  preventing  accidents,  exactly  as  its 
owner  chooses  to  prescribe,  whilst  each  workman  makes  his 
own  separate  contract  for  each  job  with  his  own  employer — 
has  been  proved,  by  a  whole  century  of  experience,  to  lead 

templation  or  furtherance  of  a  trade  dispute,  shall  be  actionable  by  reason  only 
of  the  motive  for  which  it  was  committed  or  entered  into,  or  of  there  being  no 
lawful  excuse  or  motive  for  such  act,  agreement,  combination,  or  conspiracy. 

3.  No  agreement,  combination,  or  conspiracy  by  or  on  behalf  of  an  associa- 
tion of  employers  or  a  Trade  Union  in  contemplation  or  furtherance  of  a  trade 
dispute  shall  be  indictable  as  a  crime  if  no  act  itself  punishable  as  a  crime  is 
contemplated  or  committed,  whether  as  means  or  end,   by  or  in  pursuance  of 
such  agreement,  combination,  or  conspiracy. 

4.  The  words  "trade  dispute  between  employers  and  workmen"  in  the  third 
section  of  the  Conspiracy  and  Law  of  Property  Act  of  1875  shall  therein  have 
the  same  meaning  as  "  trade  dispute"  in  this  Act. 

5.  The  words  "association  of  employers"  and   "Trade  Union"  shall,  for 
the  purposes   of  this  Act,    both   include    any   association  of  persons,    whether 
registered   or   not,  which   attempts   to   regulate  or  influence  any  or  all  of  the 
conditions  of  employment  in  one  or  more  occupations,  and  shall  also  include  any 
alliance,  federation,  or  combination  of  two  or  more  such  associations. 

6.  The   words    "trade    dispute"    shall    include    any    dispute,    difference    of 
opinion,  or  failure  of  agreement,  existing  or  contemplated,  between  one  or  more 
employers  or  an  association  of  employers,  and  one  or  more  workmen  or  a  Trade 
Union,   or  any  alliance,   federation,   or  combination    of  any  of  them,   whether 
registered  or  incorporated  or  not,  and  whether  or  not  such  dispute,  difference  of 
opinion,  or  failure  of  agreement  relates  to  the  employment  of  any  of  the  persons 
concerned,  or  to  any  pecuniary  or  other  interest  of  any  of  them,  and  whether 
they  or  any  of  them  belong  to  the  same  or  different  trades  or  places  or  societies. 

1  See  Part  III.  Chap.  i.  "The  Verdict  of  the  Economists";  Chap.  ii.  "The 
Higgling  of  the  Market";  and  Chap.  iii.  "The  Economic  Characteristics  of 
Trade  Unionism  " 


xxxvi  Industrial  Democracy 

to  "sweating."  The  necessary  Common  Rules  can  be 
enforced  only  by  two  methods,  Collective  Bargaining  and 
Legal  Enactment.  If  Collective  Bargaining,  with  its  in- 
evitable accompaniment  of  collective  abstention  from  work 
and  .occasional  stoppages  of  industry,  is,  by  the  judges' 
interpretation  of  the  law,  made  impossible,  or  even  costly 
and  difficult,  the  whole  weight  of  working-class  opinion  will 
certainly  be  thrown  in  favor  of  Legal  Enactment.  We  do 
not  ourselves  deprecate  this  course,  but  whether  Lord 
Penrhyn  and  trie  railway  companies,  the  Shipping  Federation 
and  the  engineering  employers,  would  see  any  advantage  in 
it  seems  to  us  doubtful. 

We  pass  now  to  the  second  great  change  in  Trade  Union 
environment.  Whilst  in  the  United  Kingdom  the  House  of 
Lords  has  been  making  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining 
virtually  inoperative,  the  Legislatures  of  the  young  and 
vigorous  democracies  of  Australia  and  New  Zealand  have 
been  proving  how  much  more  elastic,  and  how  much  more 
applicable  to  modern  conditions  than  has  hitherto  been 
supposed,  is  the  alternative  Method  of  Legal  Enactment. 
When  we  were  writing  in  1897,  the  legislation  of  Victoria 
and  New  Zealand  was  still  in  its  first  experimental  stage, 
and  but  little  was  known  of  its  actual  working  (see  pp.  246, 
488,  770,  776,  814).  It  has  since  been  greatly  extended 
in  scope  as  experience  has  been  gained,  and  it  has  been 
carefully  described  by  both  official  and  critical  observers. 
We  had  ourselves,  in  1898,  the  opportunity  of  seeing  both 
the  Victorian  and  the  New  Zealand  systems  at  work,  and 
we  spent  some  time  in  watching  and  inquiring,  among  friends 
and  foes  alike,  as  to  the  actual  results  of  the  experiment. 
We  are  more  than  ever  convinced  that  both  Victorian  and 
New  Zealand  statutes  deserve  favorable  consideration  by 
the  employers  and  the  statesmen,  no  less  than  by  the  work- 
men and  the  philanthropists  of  the  Mother  Country. 

The  Victorian  legislation  *  is  less  well  known  in  England 

1  The  best  account  of  the  Victorian  system  and  its  actual  working  is  the  New 
South  Wales  Government  Report  of  Royal  Commission  of  Inqziiry  into  the  Work- 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition          xxxvii 

than  that  of  New  Zealand.  By  the  Factories  and  Shops 
Act,  1896,  after  a  series  of  vain  attempts  to  put  down 
"  sweating "  by  other  means,  special  "  wage  boards "  were 
constituted  in  certain  oppressed  trades.  These  were  em- 
powered to  fix  a  minimum  standard  wage  for  the  trade,  for 
both  factory  and  outworkers,  by  time  and  by  the  piece  ; 
and  also  the  maximum  proportionate  number  of  apprentices 
or  improvers  under  eighteen  years  of  age,  and  the  minimum 
to  be  paid  to  them.  The  "  Common  Rules  "  thus  prescribed 
for  the  trade  became,  in  effect,  part  of  the  Factory  Acts, 
and  were  enforced  by  the  factory  inspectors,  like  any  other 
requirements  of  the  Acts,  by  summary  proceedings  in  the 
police  courts. 

This  Act  only  related  to  six  specially  sweated  trades, 
and  applied  only  to  Melbourne  and  its  suburbs.  In  1900, 
after  four  years'  experience,  the  law  was  widened  in  all 
directions.  The  powers  of  the  boards  were  extended  so  as 
to  cover  practically  the  whole  colony.  It  was  also  provided 
that  a  board  should  be  formed  in  any  trade  or  business  for 
which  either  House  of  Parliament  had  passed  an  approving 
resolution.  It  is  significant  of  the  appreciation  of  the  law 
that  no  fewer  than  twenty-one  more  boards  were  at  once 
constituted,  in  protected  and  unprotected  industries  alike, 
and  many  of  them  at  the  request  of  the  employers  in  the 
trades  concerned.  This  was  the  case,  for  instance,  with  the 


ing  of  Compulsory  Conciliation  and  Arbitration  Laivs  (Sydney,  1901),  by  Judge 
Backhouse.  The  laws  themselves  can  be  best  consulted  in  the  convenient 
edition  of  the  Factories  and  Shops  Acts^  by  Harrison  Ord  (Melbourne,  1900). 
A  succinct  account  of  the  system,  with  particulars  of  recent  decisions  by  the 
boards,  is  given  by  Mrs.  W.  P.  Reeves,  in  her  chapter  in  The  Case  for  the 
Factory  Acts  (London,  1901).  See  also  an  article  by  the  Hon.  W.  P. 
Reeves  in  the  Economic  Journal,  Sept.  1901,  entitled  "The  Minimum  Wage 
Law  in  Victoria  and  South  Australia " ;  the  annual  reports  of  the  Chief 
Inspector  of  Factories  (Melbourne)  for  1896-1900  inclusive;  and  the  evidence 
given  to  the  Royal  Commission  at  present  (December  1901)  sitting  to  inquire 
into  the  results  of  the  law.  The  report  of  this  Commission,  to  be  published 
shortly,  will  give  us  the  most  authoritative  account  of  the  working  of  the 
system.  It  should  be  added  that  the  Victorian  wage  board  clauses  were,  in 
December  1900,  enacted  almost  word  for  word  by  the  Legislature  of  South 
Australia. 


xxxviii  Industrial  Democracy 

boards  for  the  printers  (compositors),  carriage-builders,  cigar- 
makers,  coopers,  engravers,  saddlers,  stonecutters,  tanners, 
and  others. 

These  wage-boards  are  composed  of  between  four  and 
ten  representatives,  half  elected  by  the  employers  and  half 
by  the  operatives  in  the  particular  trade.  The  board  may 
choose  its  own  chairman,  who  has  a  casting  vote  ;  and  in 
many  of  the  trades  employers  and  employed  have  easily 
agreed  upon  a  trusted  outsider — a  judge,  a  minister  of 
religion,  or  a  responsible  government  official.  In  case  of 
disagreement  the  Government  appoints  a  chairman,  choosing 
usually  an  outsider  of  judicial  character.  The  board  then 
sets  to  work  to  determine  what  shall  be  the  standard 
minimum  rate  of  wages  in  the  trade,  and  it  is  interesting  to 
find  that,  after  a  more  or  less  protracted  but  quite  friendly 
"  higgling,"  the  representatives  have  frequently  been  able  to 
agree  on  their  decision  without  invoking  the  chairman's 
casting  vote.  The  minimum  rate  thus  fixed  may  be  made 
applicable  to  any  person  or  class  of  persons,  factory  hands 
or  outworkers,  by  time  or  by  piece  ;  and  it  is  expressly 
provided  that  the  board  is  to  take  into  consideration  "  the 
nature,  kind,  and  class  of  the  work,  and  the  mode  and 
manner  in  which  the  work  is  to  be  done,  and  the  age  and 
sex  of  the  workers,  and  any  matter  which  may  from  time  to 
time  be  prescribed."  The  board  prescribes  the  maximum 
number  of  hours,  usually  eight,  to  be  worked  for  the  daily 
wage,  and  what  minimum  rate  shall  be  paid  for  overtime, 
but  does  not  actually  limit  the  working  time  (which  is 
limited  by  law  only  for  women,  miners,  etc.).  Power  is 
reserved  to  the  Chief  Inspector  of  Factories  to  grant  to 
aged  or  infirm  workers  a  licence,  for  twelve  months  at  a 
time,  to  work  for  less  than  the  prescribed  rates,  and  he  may 
also  do  the  same  for  young  improvers  without  full  experi- 
ence. This  provision  was  added  in  the  1 900  Act,  experience 
having  shown  both  its  necessity  and  its  practicability.  It 
should  be  added  that  the  members  of  the  boards  receive  from 
public  funds  a  payment  of  ten  shillings  for  a  full  day's 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  xxxix 

session,  and  five  shillings   for  a  half-day's   session,  the  chair- 
man receiving  double  pay. 

Under  this  Act  a  legal  minimum  wage  has,  in  certain 
trades,  been  fixed  and  enforced  for  five  years,  and  in  many 
other  trades  for  a  shorter  period.  Thus,  the  minimum 
weekly  wage  for  tailoresses  was  fixed,  to  begin  with,  at 
twenty  shillings  a  week,  that  for  shirtmakers  at  sixteen 
shillings,  and  that  for  adult  male  boot  and  shoe  operatives 
at  forty-two  shillings,  these  time  rates  being  in  each  trade 
also  translated  into  equivalent  piecework  lists.  These  wages 
were  considerably  above  what  many  of  the  operatives  had 
previously  been  receiving,  but  notwithstanding  this  fact 
neither  the  volume  of  trade  nor  the  employers'  profits  appear 
to  have  been  affected.  We  could  not  ascertain  that  there 
had  been,  up  to  1898,  any  diminution  of  employment  in  the 
trades  concerned  ;  on  the  contrary,  the  numbers  at  work  had 
certainly  increased.  We  could  find  no  evidence  that  prices 
had  risen,  and  we  were  informed  by  employers  that  they  had 
not  done  so.  Nor  were  the  employers  themselves  dissatis- 
fied with  the  result.  The  explanation  of  the  paradox  lies, 
as  we  satisfied  ourselves,  in  the  very  significant  fact  that, 
when  the  employers  found  themselves  compelled  to  pay  a 
standard  wage  to  all  whom  they  employed,  they  took  care 
to  make  the  labor  as  productive  as  possible — they  chose 
their  workers  more  carefully,  kept  them  fully  employed, 
introduced  new  processes  and  machinery,  and  in  every  way 
made  the  industry  more  efficient.  The  effect  of  stopping 
competition  of  wages  is,  as  Mundella  from  practical  experi- 
ence pointed  out  over  thirty  years  ago  (see  p.  723),  to 
concentrate  it  upon  efficiency.  The  whole  experience  of 
the  Victorian  wage-boards,  alike  in  their  successes  and  in 
their  failures,  confirms  our  analysis  of  the  economic  results 
of  the  Common  Rule  (pp.  7I5-39)-1 

1  It  should  be  stated  that  this  Act,  like  all  factory  and  sanitary  laws,  has 
absolutely  failed  to  become  effective  among  the  Chinese.  Experience  in  Victoria, 
as  elsewhere,  seems  to  show  that  it  is  impossible  to  enforce  any  form  of  the 
"  National  Minimum  "  on  a  Chinese  population  in  a  white  city — a  fact  of  extreme 
significance  in  the  question  of  the  desirability  of  their  admission  or  exclusion. 


xl  Industrial  Democracy 

What  the  Victorian  law  does  is,  in  effect,  to  compel 
employers  and  workmen  to  formulate,  by  common  consent, 
minimum  conditions  for  their  own  trade,  which  can  be 
altered  when  and  as  required,  but  which  are  for  the  time 
being  enforced  by  law.  No  employer  is  compelled  to  con- 
tinue his  business,  or  to  engage  any  workman  ;  but  if  he 
chooses  to  do  so,  he  must,  as  a  minimum,  comply  with 
these  conditions,  in  exactly  the  same  way  as  he  does  with 
regard  to  the  sanitary  provisions  of  the  Factory  Acts.  No 
workman  is  compelled  to  enter  into  employment  or  for- 
bidden to  strike  for  better  terms,  but  he  is  prevented  from 
engaging  himself  for  less  than  the  minimum  wage,  exactly 
as  he  is  prevented  from  accepting  less  than  the  minimum 
sanitation.  The  law,  in  fact,  puts  every  trade  in  which  a 
wage-board  is  established  in  the  position  of  the  best  organised 
industries  in  this  country,  where  every  firm  and  every 
workman  finds  the  conditions  of  employment  effectively 
regulated  (as  regards  a  minimum)  by  a  collective  agreement 
—with  the  added  advantages  that  in  Victoria  the  enforce- 
ment of  the  Common  Rules  becomes  the  business  of  the 
professional  factory  inspector  ;  that  no  individual  can  break 
away  from  the  agreement ;  and  that  no  strikes,  picketing,  or 
other  disorderly  proceedings  are  ever  needed  to  maintain  its 
operation.  This  seems  to  us  a  distinct  advance  on  the 
anarchic  private  war  to  which  the  settlement  of  the  condi- 
tions of  employment  is  otherwise  abandoned. 

It  is  obvious  that  the  Victorian  system  brings  greater 
advantages  to  the  weaker  trades  than  to  those  strongly 
organised.  This,  to  our  mind,  is  one  of  its  merits.  The 
pressing  need  in  the  England  of  to-day  is  not  any  increase 
in  the  money  wages  of  the  better-paid  and  stronger  sections 
of  the  wage-earners,  but  a  levelling  up  of  the  oppressed  classes 
who  fall  below  the  "  Poverty  Line."  The  boilermakers  in  the 
shipbuilding  towns,  the  Lancashire  cotton-spinners,  and  the 
Northumberland  coalminers  may  do  by  their  own  strength 
(though  not  without  the  cost  of  constant  friction  and  occa- 
sional disastrous  wars),  as  much  as,  qr  more  than  any  suqh 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  xli 

law  could  do  for  them.  But  the  unskilled  laborers,  the  opera- 
tives whose  organisation  is  crippled  by  home  work,  and  the 
women  workers  everywhere,  can  never,  in  our  opinion,  by 
mere  bargaining,  obtain  either  satisfactory  Common  Rules 
or  any  real  enforcement  of  such  illusory  standards  as  they 
may  get  set  up.  We  think  that  experience  in  this  and 
other  countries  confirms  the  economic  conclusion  that  there 
is  no  way  of  raising  the  present  scandalously  low  Standard 
of  Life  of  these  classes,  except  by  some  such  legal  stiffening 
as  that  given  by  the  Victorian  law. 

We  do  not  suggest  that  the  Victorian  law  is  by  any 
means  perfect.  It  is  reported,  no  doubt  correctly,  that  it  is 
evaded  and  disobeyed  in  particular  cases,  as  is  also  the  law 
against  theft  and  murder,  but  this  we  do  not  count  as  a 
serious  objection  to  it  or  any  other  law.  The  Chief  Inspector's 
licences  to  work  under  price  are  liable  to  abuse,  but  honestly 
worked  as  the  system  now  is,  we  do  not  regard  this  excep- 
tional treatment  of  workers  actually  incapable  of  "  a  fair 
day's  work "  as  any  drawback.  It  is  anomalous  that  the 
wage-boards  should  not  be  able  to  frame  Common  Rules  as 
to  the  maximum  working  hours  and  the  many  conditions  of 
employment  other  than  wages.  More  serious  is  the  attempt 
to  limit  the  number  of  apprentices,  which — in  spite  of  the 
action  of  Lord  James  in  the  English  boot  and  shoe  manu- 
facture (pp.  482-89)  —  we  think  wholly  inexpedient  and 
prejudicial.  We  doubt,  moreover,  whether  it  will  be  found 
possible,  in  the  long-run,  to  work  a  system  of  separate 
boards  for  the  innumerable  separate  and  often  badly  defined 
trades.  Finally,  we  object  to  the  retention,  as  the  basis  of 
the  whole  law,  of  the  old  conception  that  the  amount  of  the 
wage  in  each  trade  is  a  matter  for  each  trade  to  settle 
exclusively  for  itself,  without  regard  to  the  interests  of  the 
community.  In  our  view,  the  real  justification  for  the  inter- 
ference of  the  law  is  the  injury  to  the  community  as  a  whole 
that  results  from  any  form  of  industrial  parasitism — from 
the  payment,  for  instance,  of  wages  insufficient  for  the  full 
maintenance,  under  healthy  conditions,  of  the  workers  and 


xlii  Industrial  Democracy 

their  families.  We  should,  therefore,  have  preferred  an 
explicit  statement  of  this  principle  by  the  Legislature,  exactly 
as  is  done  in  the  Factory  Acts  with  regard  to  certain  other 
conditions  of  employment,  together  with  a  definite  statutory 
minimum  wage  and  maximum  normal  day,  determined  by 
physiological  considerations,  and  not  to  be  infringed  by  any 
trade  whatsoever.1  It  would  then  have  been  possible  to 
have  limited  the  formation  of  wage-boards  to  those  occupa- 
tions in  which  the  operatives  were  alleged  to  be  working 
under  conditions  in  any  respect  worse  than  those  of  the 
"  National  Minimum  " — a  much  more  limited  task  than  that 
of  fixing  standard  rates  in  all  industries  whatsoever — and 
to  have  confined  their  scope  to  the  comparatively  easy  duty 
of  applying  the  statutory  minimum  to  the  particular  circum- 
stances of  those  trades. 

It  is  interesting  to  notice  that,  although  New  Zealand  2 
attacked  the  problem  from  the  other  end,  aiming  primarily 
at  preventing  strikes,  this  has  worked  out,  in  practice,  to 
the  Victorian  solution  of  enforcing  by  law  certain  definite 
minimum  conditions  of  employment  throughout  each  trade. 
By  the  Industrial  Conciliation  and  Arbitration  Act  of  1894, 
now  superseded  by  the  consolidating  Act  of  1900,  a  com- 
plete system  of  industrial  tribunals  was  established,  and 
empowered  to  deal  with  labor  disputes  of  all  kinds.  Taking 
the  law  as  it  now  stands,  we  find,  in  each  of  the  seven 
districts  into  which  the  Colony  is  geographically  divided,  a 

1  The  obvious  difficulties  in  the  way  of  such  a  minimum  are  dealt  with  at 
PP-  774-95- 

2  The  latest  and  most  impartial  account  of  the  New  Zealand  system  is  the 
New  South  Wales  Report  of  Royal  Commission  of  Inquiry  into  the  Working  of 
Compulsory  Conciliation  and  Arbitration  Laws  (Sydney,  1901),  by  Judge  Back- 
house.    The  Hon.  W.  P.  Reeves  (Agent-General  in  London  for  New  Zealand), 

devised  and  carried  through  the  Act  of  1894,  has  graphically  described  its 

*mg  in   The  Long  White  Cloud  (London,  1899)  and  other  works;  and  in 

rate  detail  in  his  Experiments  of  Seven  Colonies,  shortly  to  be  published. 

:e  also  A  Country  -without  Strikes  and  Newest  England,  both  by  H.  D.  Lloyd  ; 

ind   Le  Socialisms   sans  Doctrines,  by   Albert    Metin.     For  the  ablest  hostile 

the  law,  apart  from  mere  theoretical  denunciations,  the  student  must 

1  to  the  series  of  articles  in  the  Otago  Daily  Times  for  September  1901, 

by  Dr.  John  Macgregor. 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  xliii 

local  Board  of  Conciliation,  composed  of  two  members 
elected  by  the  registered  Employers'  Associations  and  two 
by  the  registered  Trade  Unions,  with  a  chairman  chosen  by 
themselves.  In  default  of  election  of  members  or  chairman, 
the  Government  appoints.  This  Board  does  not  initiate 
any  proceedings,  but  deals  with  any  local  industrial  dispute, 
whatever  the  trade,  which  may  be  referred  to  it  by  a  Trade 
Union,  an  Employers'  Association,  or  a  single  employer. 
Immediately  any  dispute  has  been,  by  either  party,  so  referred 
to  the  Board,  anything  in  the  nature  of  a  strike  or  lock-out 
is  expressly  prohibited,  under  penalty  of  .£50.  The  Board 
has  authority  to  make  full  inquiry  into  the  circumstances, 
except  that  it  cannot  compel  the  production  of  books.  It 
then  makes  suggestions  for  a  settlement.  If  these  sugges- 
tions are  accepted  by  both  parties,  they  are  embodied  in  an 
"  industrial  agreement,"  which  may  be  made  unalterable  for 
any  specified  term  not  exceeding  three  years,  and  which  in 
any  event  binds  the  parties  until  it  is  superseded  by  any 
new  agreement  or  award.  Every  such  agreement  is  now 
enforceable  by  legal  process,  with  the  same  effective  authority 
as  if  it  had  been  enacted  as  a  law.  If  the  parties  will  not 
agree  the  Board  is  to  make  a  definite  "  recommendation  "  as 
to  what,  in  its  opinion,  ought  to  be  the  settlement.  Any 
dissatisfied  party  may  thereupon,  within  a  month,  carry  the 
case  to  the  Court  of  Arbitration.  Failing  such  an  appeal, 
the  Board's  "  recommendation "  becomes  binding  on  the 
parties  as  if  it  were  an  industrial  agreement. 

The  Court  of  Arbitration  consists  of  three  members 
appointed  by  the  Government :  the  president,  a  judge  of 
the  Supreme  Court ;  and  two  persons  recommended  by  the 
Employers' Associations  and  Trade  Unions  respectively.  This 
Court  has  the  full  powers  of  an  ordinary  court  of  justice  to 
investigate  any  case  brought  before  it  by  way  of  appeal 
from  the  "  recommendation "  of  a  Board  of  Conciliation  ; 
and  is  free  to  act  according  to  "  equity  and  good  conscience  " 
without  being  bound  by  legal  pedantries.  It  makes  an 
award  in  such  terms  as  it  thinks  fit,  extending,  it  may  be, 


xliv  Industrial  Democracy 

to  a  whole  trade,  either  in  a  specified  district  or  throughout 
the  Colony,  and  including  at  its  discretion  any  related  or 
competing  industry.  The  penalty  for  breach  of  the  award 
may  be  any  sum  not  exceeding  ^500  on  an  association,  for 
payment  of  which  the  members  of  the  association  are  made 
liable  individually  up  to  ;£io  each.  Thus,  once  any  dispute 
is  referred  to  a  Board  of  Conciliation,  either  by  a  Trade 
Union  or  an  employer,  it  is  certain  to  lead,  either  by  agree- 
ment of  the  parties,  or  by  their  acceptance  of  the  "  recom- 
mendation "  of  the  Board,  or  else  by  the  authoritative 
award  of  the  Court  of  Arbitration,  to  the  enactment  of 
legally  binding  "  Common  Rules "  for  the  trade,  which 
continue  in  force  until  they  are  varied  by  subsequent  pro- 
ceedings of  a  similar  character.1 

The  evolution  of  the  New  Zealand  system,  from    1894 
to  1900,  appears  to  us  to  be  full  of  instruction.      In  its  first 

1  How  extensive  is  the  scope  of  the  authority  of  these  tribunals  may  be  seen 
from  the  definition  of  their  sphere.  They  are  to  settle  all  disputes  about 
"industrial  matters,"  and 

"'Industrial  matters'  mean  all  matters  affecting  or  relating  to  work  done, 
or  to  be  done  by  workers,  or  the  privileges,  rights,  and  duties  of  employers  or 
workers  in  any  industry,  not  involving  questions  which  are  or  may  be  the  subject 
of  proceedings  for  an  indictable  offence  ;  and  without  limiting  the  general  nature 
of  the  above  definition,  includes  all  matters  relating  to — 

"  (a)  The  wages,  allowances,  or  remuneration  of  workers  employed  in  any 
industry,  or  the  prices  paid  or  to  be  paid  therein  in  respect  of  such 
employment. 
"  (6)  The  hours  of  employment,  sex,  age,  qualification,  or  status  of  workers, 

and  the  mode,  terms,  and  conditions  of  employment. 

"  (f)  The  employment  of  children  or  young  persons,  or  of  any  person  or 
persons,  or  class  of  persons  in  any  industry,  or  the  dismissal  of  or 
refusal  to  employ  any  particular  person  or  persons  or  class  of  persons 
therein. 

"  (d)  The  claim  of  members  of  an  industrial  union  of  employers  to  preference 
of  service  from    unemployed  members   of  an    industrial    union    of 
workers. 
"  (e)  The  claim  of  members  of  industrial  unions  of  workers  to  be  employed 

in  preference  to  non-members. 
"  (/)  Any  established  custom  or  usage  of  any  industry,  either  generally  or  in 

the  particular  district  affected. 

Industry '  means  any  business,  trade,  manufacture,  undertaking,  calling 
or  employment  ^in  which  workers  are  employed. 

Worker '  means  any  person  of  any  age  or  either  sex  employed  by  any 
employer  to  do  any  skilled  or  unskilled  manual  or  clerical  work  for  hire  or  reward 
in  any  industry."— Act  of  1900. 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  xlv 

form,  the  law  aimed  ostensibly  and  primarily  at  affording 
means  by  which  labor  disputes  could  be  amicably  composed, 
and,  in  case  of  need,  compulsorily  settled  by  an  award, 
which  might,  if  certain  steps  were  taken  by  the  parties,  be 
made  enforceable  by  legal  process.  The  local  Boards  of 
Conciliation  failed,  in  two-thirds  of  the  cases  brought  before 
them,  to  bring  about  any  settlement,  one  party  or  the  other 
promptly  carrying  the  issue  to  the  Court  of  Arbitration. 
This  seems  to  have  been  due  partly  to  the  employers'  dis- 
satisfaction with  the  composition  of  the  Boards,  to  which 
they  had  at  first  refused  to  elect  members.  But  it  soon 
became  evident  that  the  workmen  valued  the  Court  of 
Arbitration  more  than  the  Boards,  for  the  very  important 
reason  that  the  award  of  the  Court  could  be  made  legally 
binding  on  the  trade,  which  was,  until  1900,  not  the  case 
with  any  decision  of  a  Board.  The  Trade  Unions,  at  first 
somewhat  cold,  became  enthusiastic  supporters  of  the  Act 
when  they  found  that,  instead  of  merely  preventing  strikes, 
it  enabled  Common  Rules  for  the  industry  to  be  made  as 
legally  binding  as  the  Factory  Acts.  They  became,  in  fact, 
as  Mr.  Reeves,  the  author  of  the  law,  admits,  "rather  too 
enthusiastic  indeed,  for  they  have  shown  a  tendency  to  make 
too  frequent  a  use  of  it."1  Every  trade  sought  to  get  its 
Common  Rules  embodied  in  law.  This,  however,  is  a  rush 
which  will  probably  exhaust  itself  as  trade  after  trade  finds 
its  conditions  settled  by  an  authoritative  award,  which  will, 
in  any  case,  need  amendment  only  on  specific  points,  and 
may  be  made  unalterable  for  a  three  years'  term.  The 
result  is,  to  use  the  words  of  a  bitter  opponent,  "  it  is 
necessary  to  put  aside  altogether  the  idea  that  our  Act  is 
simply  a  device  for  preventing  strikes.  It  is  nothing  of  the 
kind.  It  is  a  device  for  putting  the  regulation  of  trades, 
occupations,  and  industries  under  the  control  of  a  statutory 
court"  2 

Nor   do   the  employers   object.       At   first    they   usually 

1    The  Long  White  Clozid. 
2  Dr.  John  Macgregor,  of  Wellington,  New  Zealand. 


xlvi  Industrial  Democracy 

stood  aloof,  allowed  the  Government  to  appoint  their 
members  to  the  Conciliation  Boards  in  default  of  election, 
and  practically  ignored  the  Act.  But  this  attitude  was 
given  up  on  better  acquaintance  with  the  law  and  its 
working.  After  a  time  the  great  majority  of  employers 
openly  professed  their  approval  of  the  principle  of  the  Act, 
and  their  satisfaction  with  the  Court  of  Arbitration.  One 
great  captain  of  industry,  who  had  been  badly  beaten  in  the 
Court  of  Arbitration,  and  compelled  to  accept  an  award 
which  he  bitterly  resented,  candidly  confessed  to  us  in  1898 
that  he  had  since  found  that  the  peace  and  assurance  of 
peace  given  by  the  award,  together  with  the  certainty  that 
he  was  not  being  undercut  by  rival  employers,  quite  made 
up  to  him  the  increase  of  wages  he  had  been  compelled  to 
pay.  He  could  now,  he  said,  "sleep  at  night,"  confident 
that  there  would  be  no  interruption  of  his  business.  The 
enactment  of  Common  Rules  for  each  trade  has,  in  fact, 
been  discovered,  in  practice,  not  only  to  increase  produc- 
tivity, but  also  to  leave  unaffected  the  opportunities  of 
particular  employers  to  reap  the  full  advantage  of  their 
position,  connection,  or  capacity.  And  thus  we  find,  to  give 
only  one  instance,  when  the  Act  of  1900  was  before  the 
Legislature,  with  its  express  authorisation  of  the  enactment 
of  a  Legal  Minimum  Wage,  "  the  Canterbury  Employers' 
Association,"  one  of  the  most  influential  bodies  in  the  Colony, 
desiring  "  to  impress  upon  the  Government  that  they  are 
thoroughly  in  accord  with  the  principles  laid  down  in  the 
Conciliation  and  Arbitration  Act.  Any  hostility  they  may 
have  shown  in  the  past  was  mainly  due  to  the  fact  that  the 
Act  was  made  to  apply  to  a  certain  section  of  the  industrial 
community  only.  The  Government  now  propose  to  remove 
this,  and  if  the  Bill  now  before  the  House  is  amended  in  the 
direction  suggested  by  the  Association,  they  are  strongly  of 
opinion  that  it  would  be  impossible  to  conceive  of  a  more  use- 
ful measure,  properly  administered,  that  would  prove  of  such 
immense  benefit  to  all  sections  of  the  industrial  community." 
It  is,  however,  not  strictly  accurate  to  say  that  the  Act 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  xlvii 

has  prevented  all  strikes.  There  have  been  about  half  a 
dozen  small  strikes  in  New  Zealand  since  1894,  but  they 
have  all  been  among  workmen  to  whom  the  Act  had  not,  at 
the  time,  been  applied.  If  there  is  no  industrial  agreement 
or  award  in  force  in  any  trade,  a  strike  may  still  occur,  but 
it  can  be  stopped  at  once  if  the  employer  chooses  to  apply 
to  the  local  Conciliation  Board.  The  operatives  cannot 
approach  the  Board  except  in  the  capacity  of  a  Trade 
Union  or  registered  "  industrial  association,"  so  that,  in 
absolutely  unorganised  trades,  in  which  the  employers  prefer 
not  to  apply  to  the  Board,  disputes  may  still  take  place. 
As,  however,  any  seven  workers  in  any  occupation  may  form 
a  registered  association,  the  case  is  now  of  rare  occurrence. 
There  has  at  no  time  been  a  strike  in  contravention  of  an 
award  under  the  Act.  "  It  is  hardly  necessary  to  point  out," 
writes  Judge  Backhouse,  "that  the  Act  makes  no  attempt 
to  insist  on  an  employer's  carrying  on  his  business,  or  on  a 
man's  working  under  a  condition  that  he  objects  to.  All  it 
says  is  that,  where  a  Board  or  the  Court  has  interfered,  the 
business,  if  carried  on  at  all,  shall  be  carried  on  in  the 
manner  prescribed  ;  if  the  workman  works,  he  shall  work 
under  the  conditions  laid  down.  There  is  nothing  to  pre- 
vent a  strike  in  detail ;  nothing  which  will  preclude  a  man 
from  asking  for  his  time  [i.e.  wages  earned]  and  leaving." 
That  is  to  say,  the  conditions  of  employment  imposed  by 
the  New  Zealand  Court,  like  those  of  the  Victorian  wage- 
boards,  become  binding  on  the  employers  only  as  standard 
minimum  conditions,  analogous  to  those  of  the  Factory  Acts. 
By  the  end  of  1 901,  after  seven  years'  experience  of  the  system, 
with  the  one  exception  of  agriculture,  all  important  industries, 
whether  protected  by  the  tariff  or  not,  including  coal  and  gold 
mining,  the  mercantile  marine,  the  building,  textile,  and  en- 
gineering trades,  printing,  the  railway  service,  sheep-shearing, 
meat-freezing,  and  many  minor  occupations,  have  brought 
themselves  voluntarily  within  the  scope  of  the  law.  We  can 
only  add  our  personal  testimony  to  that  given  by  every  careful 
investigator  into  the  circumstances  of  New  Zealand,  that  there 

d 


xlviii  Industrial  Democracy 

is,  so  far,  no  evidence  of  injury  to  its  industrial  prosperity;  that 
after  seven  years'  trial,  there  is  no  party — scarcely  even  any 
section  of  a  party — advocating  or  desiring  the  repeal  of  the 
law  ;  that  it  is,  on  the  contrary,  almost  universally  approved 
of  by  employers  as  well  as  workmen  ;  and  that  there  is 
every  indication  that  its  operation  has  been  of  great  and 
enduring  benefit  to  the  community  as  a  whole.  The  world 
is  certainly  indebted  to  New  Zealand — and,  in  particular,  to 
Mr.  W.  P.  Reeves — for  an  original  and  highly  significant 
object  lesson  in  labor  legislation.  It  may  be  added  that 
New  South  Wales  and  Western  Australia,  after  elaborate  in- 
vestigation and  prolonged  discussion,  enacted,  in  1900-1901, 
laws  following  closely  the  text  of  that  of  New  Zealand. 

The  differences  between  the  Victorian  and  New  Zealand 
systems  are  full  of  interest.  In  Victoria  the  wage-board, 
once  established,  itself  takes  the  initiative,  and  immediately 
sets  to  work,  without  waiting  for  a  dispute,  to  frame  Common 
Rules  for  the  whole  trade.  The  New  Zealand  tribunals 
cannot  themselves  initiate  proceedings,  and  must  wait  until 
a  dispute — -which  means,  in  practice,  a  mere  refusal  by  em- 
ployer or  Trade  Union  of  the  other's  request — is  expressly 
referred  to  them.  But  once  any  occupation  in  New  Zealand 
has  come  under  an  industrial  agreement  or  an  award,  though 
the  terms  may  be  indefinitely  varied  from  time  to  time,  some 
"  Common  Rules  "  for  the  trade  will  practically  always  exist. 
In  Victoria,  again,  the  award  of  the  wage-board  can  never  be 
anything  but  a  minimum.  It  can  contain  nothing  to  prevent 
an  employer  from  offering  better  terms,  or  a  Trade  Union 
from  striking  to  get  better  terms.  In  New  Zealand  the  law 
originally  contained  no  mention  of  a  minimum  wage,  and 
though  this  is  now  expressly  authorised  by  the  statute,  there  is 
theoretically  nothing  to  prevent  the  tribunals  (like  the  justices 
under  the  Elizabethan  statutes)  from  enacting  precise  rates  or 
conditions,  which  would  be  maxima  as  well  as  minima,  for- 
bidding employers  to  offer  more,  and  binding  the  Trade  Union 
not  merely  to  abstain  from  a  strike,  but  also  to  refrain  from 
collectively  asking  for  better  terms,  or  conspiring  to  obtain 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  xlix 

them  by  a  concerted  refusal  to  renew  contracts  of  service. 
In  practice,  however,  the  New  Zealand  awards  are  always 
worded  as  minima,  not  as  maxima — a  distinction  which  we 
regard  as  vitally  important  to  the  interest  of  the  community, 
as  well  as  to  that  of  the  wage-earners,  as  the  enactment 
of  any  maximum  discourages  efficiency  and  stops  all  pro- 
gress. There  is,  in  fact,  no  real  difference  between  the 
Colonies  on  this  point,  as  it  was,  from  the  first,  taken  for 
granted  in  New  Zealand  that  the  agreements  and  awards 
must  take  the  form  only  of  minimum  conditions,  seeing  that 
any  individual  workman  above  the  lowest  grade  of  efficiency 
could,  even  with  a  maximum,  always  have  resorted  to  the 
"  strike  in  detail "  as  a  means  of  enforcing  his  "  rent  of 
ability."  The  point  is,  however,  of  such  vital  importance 
that  we  should  prefer  to  see  the  tribunal  expressly  limited  to 
the  enactment  of  minimum,  not  maximum  conditions.  A 
more  practical  difference  between  the  two  Colonies  is  that, 
in  Victoria,  the  enforcement  of  the  prescribed  minimum 
becomes  the  duty  of  the  Government,  through  its  factory 
inspectors,  and  breaches  of  the  award  are  proceeded  against, 
at  the  public  expense,  in  the  police  courts.  In  New  Zea- 
land the  enforcement  of  the  award  is  left  to  the  vigilance  of 
the  parties  concerned,  and  the  necessary  legal  proceedings 
are  at  their  own  expense,  and  take  place  only  in  the  Court 
of  Arbitration.  In  Victoria  each  trade  must  have  its  own 
board,  which  now  acts  for  the  whole  of  that  trade  through- 
out the  Colony.  In  New  Zealand,  though  there  is  provision 
for  the  appointment,  by  way  of  exception,  of  special  boards 
for  particular  cases,  this  has  not  been  taken  advantage  of, 
and  each  district  has  its  own  local  board,  dealing  with  all 
the  trades  in  that  district,  whilst  a  single  Court  of  Arbitra- 
tion deals  with  all  trades  all  over  the  Colony.  Finally,  we 
have  the  highly  significant  difference  that,  whereas  in 
Victoria  the  settlement  of  the  conditions  of  employment  is 
regarded  as  entirely  a  matter  for  the  trade  concerned,  with- 
out opportunity  of  appeal,  in  New  Zealand  they  are  dealt 
with  by  tribunals  of  first  instance  and  a  court  of  appeal,  both 


1  Indiistrial  Democracy 

representing,  not  the  trade  concerned,  but  the  community 
as  a  whole,  and  thus  charged  to  have  regard  to  the  para- 
mount interest  which  the  public  has  in  the  maintenance 
and  progressive  advance,  alike  of  the  operatives'  Standard  of 
Life  and  of  industrial  productivity.  It  is  the  conscious 
adoption  of  this  latter  principle,  by  public  opinion  and  the 
Legislatures  of  three  such  important  states  as  New  Zealand, 
New  South  Wales,  and  Western  Australia,  that  we  regard 
as  the  most  important  feature  of  these  proceedings. 

We  venture  to  forecast  some  of  the  changes  in  Trade 
Union  structure  and  function  which  will  be  brought  about 
by  these  alterations  in  its  environment.  First  and  foremost 
we  anticipate  a  change  among  Trade  Unionists  in  their 
appreciation  of  the  relative  merits  of  Collective  Bargaining 
and  Legal  Enactment  (pp.  253-57).  Collective  Bargaining 
necessarily  implies  the  alternative  of  a  collective  refusal  to 
come  to  terms,  that  is  to  say,  a  strike  or  lock-out.  But  the 
decisions  of  the  judges  go  very  far  in  the  direction  of 
making  a  strike  impossible.  A  Trade  Union  may,  it  is 
true,  still  lawfully  conduct  a  strike,  provided  that  it  is 
carried  out  without  a  breach  of  the  peace  ;  without  threaten- 
ing any  employer  that  his  business  will  be  temporarily 
brought  to  a  standstill  ;  without  causing  any  damage  to 
third  parties ;  without  publishing  anything  that,  though 
true,  is  technically  libellous ;  without  obstructing  the 
thoroughfare,  or  "  watching  and  besetting  "  any  place  ;  and 
without  even  any  two  men  trying,  in  concert,  peacefully  to 
persuade  a  blackleg  to  remain  loyal  to  his  order.  There 
may  be  a  few  Trade  Unions,  such  as  the  Lancashire  Cotton- 
spinners,  the  Northumberland  Coalminers,  or  the  ship- 
building Boilermakers  which  (able  as  they  are  to  enforce 
compulsory  membership  on  all  persons  working  at  the 
trade,  and  so  highly  skilled  as  to  be  incapable  of  being 
replaced)  could  successfully  conduct  a  strike  under  these 
conditions,  without  rinding  their  funds  denuded  by  law 
expenses  and  damages.  But  the  vast  majority  of  Trade 
Unions  comprise  only  a  part  of  the  workers  in  their  trades, 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  li 

and  in  many  cases  it  would  be  possible,  in  an  emergency, 
for  the  employers  to  get  workers  of  other  trades  to  replace 
them.  With  Trade  Unions  of  this  kind  every  strike 
inevitably  leads  to  proceedings  which,  though  not  criminal, 
may  now  be  held  actionable.  Moreover,  Trade  Unions  are 
becoming  every  day  more  conscious  of  the  fact  that,  for  the 
great  mass  of  manual  workers  who  exist  below  the  "  Poverty 
Line,"  even  this  amount  of  collective  action  is  impracticable. 
To  the  underfed,  badly  housed,  and  overworked  man  or 
woman,  deprived  of  the  leisure  as  well  as  of  the  strength 
necessary  for  organisation — to  the  isolated  outworker  or 
assistant  in  the  small  workshop — Collective  Bargaining  is 
wholly  and  for  ever  out  of  the  question.  All  these  con- 
siderations are  cutting  at  the  root  of  that  buoyant  faith  of 
the  older  Trade  Unionists  in  the  abstract  "  right  of  combina- 
tion," by  which  they  meant  the  right  to  a  free  fight  with 
the  employers.  On  the  other  hand,  the  success  of  the 
Colonial  experiments  is  rapidly  opening  the  eyes  of  English 
employers  and  workmen  to  new  ways  of  using  the  Method 
of  Legal  Enactment,  and  new  advantages  of  its  application. 
For  instance,  the  word  "  arbitration "  has,  in  the  course  of 
four  years,  completely  changed  its  common  meaning. 
When  we  wrote  our  chapter  on  Arbitration  (pp.  222-45) 
we  could  still  use  the  term  exclusively  for  a  voluntary 
recourse  to  a  voluntarily  chosen  tribunal  whose  award  was 
only  voluntarily  accepted.  Now  arbitration  in  labor  disputes 
has  come  to  mean,  in  most  people's  minds,  merely  a  par- 
ticular form  of  social  machinery  by  which  the  conditions 
of  employment  can  be  authoritatively  settled,  and  strikes 
prevented,  whether  individual  employers  or  individual  work- 
men like  it  or  not.  The  interesting  differences  between 
the  systems  of  New  Zealand  and  Victoria,  with  their 
equally  interesting  imitations  in  New  South  Wales,  Western 
Australia,  and  South  Australia,  show  how  elastic  and  how 
closely  applicable  to  the  details  of  each  trade  and  town  the 
once  rigid  law  may  be. 

Passing  now  from  the  "  methods  "  to  the  "  regulations  " 


Hi  Industrial  Democracy 

of  Trade  Unionism,  we  look  for  even  greater  changes.  Our 
analysis  of  these  regulations  showed  that  they  fell,  for  all 
their  multifariousness,  into  two  classes — the  Device  of  the 
Common  Rule  and  the  Device  of  Restriction — classes  which 
are  sharply  marked  off  from  each  other,  which  rest  on 
absolutely  different  assumptions,  and  which  are  mutually 
contradictory  in  their  social  results.  We  showed  that 
economic  science  found  nothing  to  condemn  in  the  Device 
of  the  Common  Rule ;  that,  in  fact,  in  all  regulations 
based  on  this  principle  —  notably  those  relating  to  the 
Standard  Rate,  the  Normal  Day,  and  prescribed  conditions 
of  Sanitation  and  Safety — Trade  Unionism  positively  pro- 
moted efficiency,  stimulated  both  workmen  and  employers 
to  greater  productivity,  and  tended  constantly  to  improve 
both  human  character  and  technical  processes.  On  the 
other  hand,  we  demonstrated  that  the  regulations  based 
on  the  Device  of  Restriction  —  whether  of  numbers  or 
output,  whether  in  the  use  of  machinery  or  in  transformation 
of  processes — were  wholly  injurious  not  only  to  the  trade 
concerned  and  to  the  community  as  a  whole,  but  also  to 
the  manual  worker  himself.  It  is  to  be  counted  as  one  of 
the  great  merits  of  British  Trade  Unionism  that  it  has, 
during  the  past  hundred  years,  with  practically  no  outside 
assistance,  been  steadily  subordinating  and  discarding  the 
Device  of  Restriction,  which  it  had  inherited  partly  from 
the  regulations  of  the  Craft  Gilds  and  partly  from  the 
instincts  of  unorganised  hired  labor ;  substituting  for  it, 
as  we  proved  with  reference  to  trade  after  trade,  its  own 
characteristic  invention  of  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule. 
Already,  in  1897,  we  were  able  to  show  that  the  Device  of 
the  Common  Rule  was,  in  British  Trade  Unionism,  both 
the  predominant  and  the  growing  element,  whilst  the 
Device  of  Restriction  lingered  only  in  a  minority  of  trades, 
in  which  it  was  becoming  steadily  more  discredited. 

This  eminently  desirable  tendency  will  now,  it  is  clear, 
receive  a  great  stimulus.  Public  opinion  so  keenly  appre- 
ciates the  danger  of  German  and  American  rivalry  in 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  liii 

industry,  and  international  competition  is  becoming  so 
intense  and  all-pervading,  that  every  kind  of  limitation  or 
restriction  of  productive  power  is  seen  to  be  almost  criminal. 
What  with  law  and  popular  disapproval,  and  the  better 
instruction  of  the  workmen  themselves,  to  which  Trade 
Unionism  has  so  much  contributed,  we  expect  to  see  the 
remnants  of  the  Device  of  Restriction — especially  all  forms 
of  Restriction  of  Numbers — rapidly  disappear  from  the 
Trade  Union  world.  Restriction  of  effort,  and  reluctance 
to  make  the  most  of  machinery — already  extinct  in  the 
trades  governed  by  collectively-agreed-to  Standard  Lists  of 
Piecework  Prices — will  linger  longest  in  those  occupations 
in  which  either  timework  or  competitive  piecework  survives, 
and  in  which  the  employers  refuse  or  neglect  to  set  their 
brains  to  work,  in  conjunction  with  the  Trade  Union 
officials,  to  devise  more  intelligent  methods  of  remuneration. 
In  such  trades  employers  and  workmen  alike  will  continue 
to  suffer  the  consequences  of  their  own  stupidity. 

On  the  other  hand,  the  decisive  approval  which  economic 
science  gives  to  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule  is  reinforced 
by  the  growing  public  appreciation  of  the  national  import- 
ance of  preventing  every  kind  of  "  sweating."  As  a  nation 
we  are  becoming  keenly  conscious  of  the  fact  that  the 
existence  of  whole  classes  who  are  chronically  underfed, 
ill-clothed,  badly  housed,  and  overworked,  constitutes  not 
only  a  grievance  to  these  unfortunates  themselves,  but  also 
a  serious  drain  upon  the  vitality  and  productivity  of  the 
community  as  a  whole.  The  only  effective  way  to  prevent 
the  national  loss  involved  in  the  existence  of  "  parasitic 
trades  "  is  seen  to  be  the  compulsory  extension  to  them  of 
those  Common  Rules  which  the  stronger  trades  have  got 
for  themselves.  The  idea  of  a  compulsorily  enforced 
"  National  Minimum " — already  embodied  in  our  law  as 
regards  sanitation  and  education — is  now  seen  to  be  appli- 
cable as  regards  rest  and  subsistence.  And  just  at  the  time 
when  the  successful  experiments  of  Victoria  and  New 
Zealand  have  been  proving  to  us  that  a  Legal  Minimum 


liv  Industrial  Democracy 

Wage  is  not  at  all  an  impossibility,  and  that  it  actually 
works,  and  works  well,  there  comes  the  new  Act  of  the 
New  South  Wales  Legislature,  with  its  express  adoption  of 
the  principle,  under  the  very  name  that  we  invented  for  it 
four  years  ago.  By  this  statute,  passed  in  December  1901, 
at  the  instance  of  Mr.  Bernhard  Wise,  the  Court  of  Arbitra- 
tion is  empowered  to  declare  that  any  practice,  usage, 
condition  of  employment,  or  industrial  dealing  shall,  with 
such  limitations  and  exceptions  as  the  Court  may  declare, 
become  a  "  Common  Rule  "  for  all  persons  employed  in  the 
industry  under  consideration,  to  be  henceforth  obeyed  by 
every  employer,  and  to  be  enforced  by  drastic  penalties. 

One  probable  application  of  the  policy  of  the  National 
Minimum  seems  to  us  so  urgently  required  for  national  safety 
that  we  give  it  special  prominence.  Perhaps  the  gravest 
social  symptom  at  the  opening  of  the  twentieth  century  is 
the  lack  of  physical  vigor,  moral  self-control,  and  technical 
skill  of  the  town-bred,  manual-working  boy.  In  the  indus- 
trial organisation  of  to-day  there  are  hundreds  of  thousands 
of  youths,  between  fourteen  and  twenty-one,  who  are  taken 
on  by  employers  to  do  unskilled  and  undisciplined  work,  at 
comparatively  high  wages  for  mere  boys,  who  are  taught  no 
trade,  who  are  kept  working  long  hours  at  mere  routine,  and 
who  are  habitually  turned  adrift,  to  recruit  the  ranks  of 
unskilled  labor,  as  soon  as  they  require  a  man's  subsistence 
(pp.  482-85,  704-15,  768-69,  811).  We  see  four  acute 
evils  arising  out  of  the  existence  of  this  class.  Ministers  of 
religion  deplore  the  "  hooliganism  "  of  our  great  cities.  No 
less  serious  is  the  physical  degeneracy,  which  is  leading  our 
military  advisers  to  declare  that  60  per  cent  of  the  adult 
male  population  now  fail  to  reach  the  already  low  standard 
of  the  recruiting  sergeant.  At  the  same  time,  there  is  a 
constant  deficiency  in  the  supply  of  highly  skilled  labor, 
whilst  all  educationists  agree  that  it  is  impossible  to  give 
adequate  technical  training  with  such  voluntary  attendance  as 
can  be  got  from  lads  after  ten  or  twelve  hours'  employment 
(p.  77°)-  Finally,  in  this  suppression  of  the  adult  male 


Introduction  to  the  1902  Edition  Iv 

operative  by  successive  relays  of  boys  between  fourteen  and 
twenty-one,  we  have,  as  we  have  shown  (pp.  482-89,  768-7  i), 
one  of  the  most  insidious  forms  of  industrial  parasitism.  From 
the  point  of  view  of  the  community,  we  cannot  afford  to 
regard  the  growing  boy  as  an  independent  wealth-producer, 
to  be  satisfied  by  a  daily  subsistence  :  he  is  the  future  citizen 
and  parent,  for  whom,  up  to  twenty-one,  proper  conditions 
of  growth  and  training  are  of  paramount  importance.  Every 
industry  employing  boy-labor,  and  not  providing  adequate 
physical  and  mental  training,  is  using  up  the  stock  of  the  nation, 
and  comes  under  condemnation  as  a  parasitic  trade  (p.  771). 

Now,  although  philanthropists  and  statesmen  have  de- 
plored this  complex  evil,  no  systematic  treatment  of  it 
has  yet  been  undertaken.  The  Trade  Unions,  to  whom  it 
presents  itself  primarily  as  the  increase  of  "  boy-labor,"  have 
found  no  better  device  against  it  than  the  so-called  "  appren- 
ticeship "  regulations  (pp.  482-89).  But  the  old  system  of 
individual  apprenticeship  to  the  master  craftsman,  with  its 
anomalous  restrictions  of  age  and  number,  and  its  haphazard 
amateur  instruction,  is,  as  regards  nearly  all  trades,  dead 
and  past  reviving.  Any  attempt  to  resuscitate  it  inevitably 
takes  the  form  of  a  mere  limitation  of  numbers,  or  other 
narrowing  of  the  entrance  to  a  trade — a  policy  which,  as  we 
have  demonstrated,  does  not  cure  the  evil,  and  is  seriously 
prejudicial  to  masters  and  men  alike,  to  the  trade  itself,  and 
to  the  whole  community  (pp.  454-89,  768-71).  Unfortu- 
nately, this  limitation  of  the  number  of  apprentices  has  now 
been  embodied  in  both  New  Zealand  and  Victorian  law, 
and  we  desire  therefore  to  draw  pointed  attention,  not  only 
to  the  utter  futility  of  this  device,  but  also  to  the  existence 
of  a  more  excellent  way. 

We  see  no  remedy  for  the  grave  social  evils  resulting 
from  the  illegitimate  use  of  boy-labor,  and  the  consequent 
industrial  parasitism,  except  in  an  appropriate  application  of 
the  Policy  of  the  National  Minimum  (pp.  770-71).  The 
nation  must,  at  any  inconvenience,  prevent  such  conditions 
of  employment  of  boys  as  are  demonstrably  inconsistent 


Ivi  Industrial  Democracy 

with  the  maintenance  of  the  race  in  a  state  of  efficiency  as 
producers  and  citizens.  As  regards  youths  under  twenty-one 
the  community  is  bound,  in  its  own  interest,  to  secure  for 
them,  not  as  at  present,  daily  subsistence  and  pocket-money, 
but  such  conditions  of  nurture  as  will  allow  of  the  con- 
tinuous provision,  generation  after  generation,  of  healthy  and 
efficient  adults.  What  is  required  for  the  "  hooligan "  is 
adequate  opportunity  for  physical  culture  and  effective 
technical  training,  and  the  systematic  enforcement  of  these 
by  law.  This  means,  we  suggest,  an  extension  of  the  exist- 
ing "  half-time  "  system.  We  see  no  reason  why  the  present 
prohibition  to  employ  a  boy  in  a  factory  or  workship  for 
more  than  thirty  hours  in  a  week  should  not  be  extended 
to  all  occupations,  and  at  least  up  to  the  age  of  eighteen. 
The  twenty  or  thirty  hours  per  week  thus  saved  from  in- 
dustrial employment  should  be  compulsorily  devoted  to  a 
properly  organised  course  of  physical  training  and  technical 
education,  which  could,  under  such  circumstances,  be  carried 
out  with  a  thoroughness  and  efficiency  hitherto  undreamt  of. 
Meanwhile  employers  would  remain  free  to  engage  boys,  but 
as  they  could  get  them  only  for  half-time,  they  would  not 
be  tempted  to  hire  them  except  for  the  legitimate  purpose  of 
training  up  a  new  generation  of  craftsmen.  Finally,  we  may 
add  that  if  at  any  time  it  should  be  deemed  necessary  for 
the  purpose  of  home  defence  to  have  the  nation  trained  to 
arms,  a  mere  extension  of  such  a  half-time  system  to  the 
age  of  twenty-one  would  enable  every  citizen  to  be  drilled 
and  taught  the  use  of  the  rifle  without  the  slightest  interrup- 
tion of  wage-earning  or  any  segregation  in  barracks.  We 
suggest  that  the  "citizen-army"  of  the  future  will,  in  the 
United  Kingdom,  more  probably  take  this  form  than  that  of 
conscription  by  ballot  or  any  universal  military  service  for 
one  or  two  years  at  a  stretch. 

SIDNEY  AND  BEATRICE  WEBB. 

41  GROSVENOR  ROAD,  WESTMINSTER, 
LONDON,  December  1901. 


CONTENTS 

PART    I 
TRADE    UNION   STRUCTURE 

CHAPTER    I 

PAGE 

PRIMITIVE  DEMOCRACY       .         .         ...         .         .  3 

CHAPTER    II 

REPRESENTATIVE  INSTITUTIONS  .  .         .         .  38 

CHAPTER    III 
THE  UNIT  OF  GOVERNMENT      .         .         .         .         .         .  72 

CHAPTER  IV 

INTERUNION    RELATIONS 104 

PART    II 
TRADE   UNION   FUNCTION 

CHAPTER    I 

INTRODUCTION  ....  MS 

THE  METHOD  OF  MUTUAL  INSURANCE     .         .         .         .  152 


Iviii  Industrial  Democracy 


CHAPTER    II 

PAGE 

THE  METHOD  OF  COLLECTIVE  BARGAINING  173 

CHAPTER  III 
ARBITRATION      ......  222 

CHAPTER    IV 
THE  METHOD  OF  LEGAL  ENACTMENT        .         .         .         .         247 

CHAPTER  V 
THE  STANDARD  RATE        .         .         .         .         .         .         .         279 

CHAPTER    VI 
THE  NORMAL  DAY    ........         324 

CHAPTER   VII 
SANITATION  AND  SAFETY   .         .         .         .         .         .         .         354 

CHAPTER   VIII 
NEW  PROCESSES  AND  MACHINERY     .....         392 

CHAPTER    IX 
CONTINUITY  OF  EMPLOYMENT    ......         430 


PART   II 
TRADE   UNION   FUNCTION— Continued 

CHAPTER   X 

PAGE 

THE  ENTRANCE  TO  A  TRADE    .         .         .  .         .  -453 

(a)  APPRENTICESHIP  .         .    -     .         .  .         .  .         454 

(b}  THE  LIMITATION  OF  BOY-LABOR   .  .         .  .482 

(<:)  PROGRESSION  WITHIN  THE  TRADE  . .         .  .         489 

(d)  THE  EXCLUSION  OF  WOMEN         .  .         .  .         495 

CHAPTER    XI 

THE  RIGHT  TO  A  TRADE  .         .....  .         .  .         508 

CHAPTER    XII 

THE  IMPLICATIONS  OF  TRADE  UNIONISM   .  .       ".  .  .      528 

CHAPTER   XIII 

THE  ASSUMPTIONS  OF  TRADE  UNIONISM    .  •-.  ,<     .  .         559 


lx  Industrial  Democracy 

PART    III 
TRADE   UNION   THEORY 

CHAPTER    I 

PAGE 

THE  VERDICT  OF  THE  ECONOMISTS   .         .  6°3 

CHAPTER   II 
THE  HIGGLING  OF  THE  MARKET       .  654 

CHAPTER    III 
THE  ECONOMIC  CHARACTERISTICS  OF  TRADE  UNIONISM    .         703 

(a)  THE  DEVICE  OF  RESTRICTION  OF  NUMBERS          .         704 

(b)  THE  DEVICE  OF  THE  COMMON  RULE    .        .         .         715 

(c)  THE  EFFECT  OF  THE  SECTIONAL  APPLICATION  OF  THE 

COMMON  RULE  ON  THE  DISTRIBUTION  OF  INDUSTRY         740 

(d)  PARASITIC  TRADES 749 

(e)  THE  NATIONAL  MINIMUM     .....         766 

(/)  THE  UNEMPLOYABLE '        784 

(g)  SUMMARY  OF  THE  ECONOMIC  CHARACTERISTICS  OF 

THE    DEVICE   OF   THE    COMMON    RULE   .  .  .  789 

(//)  TRADE  UNION  METHODS       .....         796 

CHAPTER    IV 
TRADE  UNIONISM  AND  DEMOCRACY  .         .  .  807 


Contents  Ixi 

APPENDICES 

PAGE 

I. — THE  LEGAL  POSITION  OF  COLLECTIVE  BARGAINING  IN 

ENGLAND    .........         853 

II. — THE  BEARING  OF  INDUSTRIAL  PARASITISM  AND  THE 
POLICY  OF  A  NATIONAL  MINIMUM  ON  THE  FREE  TRADE 
CONTROVERSY  ........  863 

III. — SOME  STATISTICS  BEARING  ON  THE  RELATIVE  MOVE- 
MENTS OF  THE  MARRIAGE  AND  BIRTH-RATES,  PAUPER- 
ISM, WAGES,  AND  THE  PRICE  OF  WHEAT  .  .  .  873 

IV. — A   SUPPLEMENT   TO   THE    BIBLIOGRAPHY   OF   TRADE 

UNIONISM 878 

INDEX  .  .......        901 


PART    I 
TRADE    UNION    STRUCTURE 


VOL.  I 


CHAPTER    I 


PRIMITIVE    DEMOCRACY 


IN  the  local  trade  clubs  of  the  eighteenth  century, 
democracy  appeared  in  its  simplest  form.  Like  the  citizens 
of  Uri  or  Appenzell 2  the  workmen  were  slow  to  recognise 
any  other  authority  than  "  the  voices "  of  all  concerned. 
The  members  of  each  trade,  in  general  meeting  assembled, 
themselves  made  the  regulations,  applied  them  to  particular 
cases,  voted  the  expenditure  of  funds,  and  decided  on 
such  action  by  individual  members  as  seemed  necessary 
for  the  common  weal.  The  early  rules  were  accordingly 
occupied  with  securing  the  maintenance  of  order  and 
decorum  at  these  general  meetings  of  "  the  trade "  or 
"  the  body."  With  this  view  the  president,  often  chosen 
only  for  the  particular  meeting,  was  treated  with  great 
respect  and  invested  with  special,  though  temporary, 

1  Copyright  in  the  United  States  of  America,  1896,  by  Sidney  and  Beatrice 
Webb. 

2  The  early  Trade  Union  general  meetings  have,  indeed,  many  interesting 
resemblances,  both  in  spirit  and  in  form,  to  the  "  Landesgemeinden,"  or  general 
meetings  of  all  citizens,  of  the  old  Swiss  Cantons.     The  best  description  of  these 
archaic  Swiss  democracies,  as  they  exist  to-day,  is  given  by  Eugene  Rambert  in 
his  work  Les  Alpes  Suisses :  Etudes  Historiques  et  Nationales  (Lausanne,  1889). 
J.  M.  Vincent's  State  and  Federal  Government  in  Switzerland  (Baltimore,  1891) 
is  more  precise  and  accurate  than  any  other  account  in  the  English  language. 
Freeman's  picturesque  reference  to  them  in  The  Growth  of  the  English  Constitu- 
tion (London,  1872)  is  well  known. 


4  Trade  Union  Structure 

authority.  Thus  the  constitution  of  the  London  Society 
of  Woolstaplers,  established  1785,  declares  "that  at  every 
meeting  of  this  society  a  president  shall  be  chosen  to 
preserve  the  rules  of  decorum  and  good  order ;  and  if  any 
member  should  not  be  silent  on  due  notice  given  by  the 
president,  which  shall  be  by  giving  three  distinct  knocks  on 
the  table,  he  shall  fine  threepence  ;  and  if  any  one  shall  in- 
terrupt another  in  any  debate  while  addressing  the  president, 
he  shall  fine  sixpence ;  and  if  the  person  so  fined  shall 
return  any  indecent  language,  he  shall  fine  sixpence  more  ; 
and  should  any  president  misconduct  himself,  so  as  to  cause 
uproar  and  confusion  in  the  society,  or  shall  neglect  to 
enforce  a  strict  observance  of  this  and  the  following  article, 
he  shall  be  superseded,  and  another  president  shall  be  chosen 
in  his  stead.  The  president  shall  be  accommodated  with 
his  own  choice  of  liquors,  wine  only  excepted." x  And  the 
Articles  of  the  Society  of  Journeymen  Brushmakers,  to 
which  no  person  was  to  be  admitted  as  a  member  "  who  is 
not  well-affected  to  his  present  Majesty  and  the  Protestant 
succession,  and  in  good  health,  and  of  a  respectable  char- 
acter," provide  "  that  on  each  evening  the  society  meets  there 
shall  be  a  president  chosen  from  the  members  present  to 
keep  order ;  to  be  allowed  a  shilling  for  his  trouble  ;  any 
member  refusing  to  serve  the  office  to  be  fined  sixpence.  If 
any  member  dispute  on  politics,  swear,  lay  wagers,  promote 
gambling,  or  behave  otherwise  disorderly,  and  will  not  be 
silent  when  ordered  by  the  chairman,  he  shall  pay  a  fine  of 
a  shilling." 2 

The  rules  of  every  old  society  consist  mainly  of  safe- 
guards of  the  efficiency  of  this  general  meeting.  Whilst 
political  or  religious  wrangling,  seditious  sentiments  or  songs, 
cursing,  swearing,  or  obscene  language,  betting,  wagering, 
gaming,  or  refusing  to  keep  silence  were  penalised  by  fines, 
elaborate  and  detailed  provision  was  made  for  the  entertain- 

1  The  Articles  of  the  London  Society  of  Woolstaplers  (London,  1813). 

2  Articles  of  the  Society  of  Journeymen  Brushmakers,  held  at  the  sign  of  the 
Craven  Head,  Drury  Lane  (London,  1806). 


Primitive  Democracy  5 

ment  of  the  members.  Meeting,  as  all  clubs  did,  at  a  public- 
house  in  a  room  lent  free  by  the  landlord,  it  was  taken  as 
a  matter  of  course  that  each  man  should  do  his  share  of 
drinking.  The  rules  often  prescribe  the  sum  to  be  spent  at 
each  meeting  :  in  the  case  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Iron- 
founders,  for  instance,  the  member's  monthly  contribution  in 
1809  was  a  shilling  "  to  the  box,"  and  threepence  for  liquor, 
"  to  be  spent  whether  present  or  not."  The  Brushmakers 
provided  "that  on  every  meeting  night  each  member  shall 
receive  a  pot  ticket  at  eight  o'clock,  a  pint  at  ten,  and 
no  more." l  And  the  Manchester  Compositors  resolved 
in  1826  "  that  tobacco  be  allowed  to  such  members  of  this 
society  as  require  it  during  the  hours  of  business  at  any 
meeting  of  the  society."  2 

After  the  president,  the  most  important  officers  were, 
accordingly,  the  stewards  or  marshalmen,  two  or  four  members 
usually  chosen  by  rotation.  Their  duty  was,  to  use  the 
words  of  the  Cotton-spinners,  "  at  every  meeting  to  fetch  all 
the  liquor  into  the  committee  room,  and  serve  it  regularly 
round  "  ; 3  and  the  members  were,  in  some  cases,  "  forbidden 
to  drink  out  of  turn,  except  the  officers  at  the  table  or 
a  member  on  his  first  coming  into  the  town." 4  Treasurer 

1  The  account  book  of  the  little  Preston  Society  of  Carpenters,  whose  mem- 
bership in  1807  averaged  about  forty-five,  shows  an  expenditure  at  each  meeting 
of  6s.    to   75.    6d.      As  late  as  1837   the   rules   of  the    Steam-Engine  Makers' 
Society  provided  that  one-third  of  the  income — fourpence  out   of  the  monthly 
contribution  of  a  shilling — "shall  be  spent  in  refreshments.   .   .   .   To  prevent 
disorder  no  person  shall  help  himself  to  any  drink  in  the  club-room  during  club 
hours,   but   what  is  served  him  by  the   waiters  or  marshalmen   who    shall  be 
appointed  by  the  president  every  club  night."     Some  particulars  as  to  the  dying 
away  of  this  custom  are  given  in  our  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  185,  186  ; 
see  also  the  article  by  Prof.  W.  J.  Ashley  on  "Journeymen's  clubs,"  in  Political 
Science  Quarterly,  March  1897. 

2  MS.  Minutes  of  the  Manchester  Typographical  Society,  7th  March  1826. 

3  Articles,  Rules,   Orders,  and  Regulations  made  and  to  be  observed  by  and 
between  the  Friendly  Associated  Cotton- spinners  within  the  township  of  Oldham 
(Oldham,  1797  :  reprinted  1829). 

4  Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders,  Rules,  1809.     The  Rules  of  the  Liverpool 
Shipwrights'  Society  of  1784  provided  also  "  that  each  member  that  shall  call  for 
drink  without  leave  of  the  stewards  shall  forfeit  and  pay  for  the  drink  they  call  for 
to  the  stewards  for  the  use  of  the  box.  . . .  That  the  marshalmen  shall  pay  the  over- 
plus of  drink  that  comes  in  at  every  monthly  meeting  more  than  allowed  by  ths 


6  Trade  Union  Stritcture 

there  was  often  none,  the  scanty  funds,  if  not  consumed 
as  quickly  as  collected,  being  usually  deposited  with  the 
publican  who  acted  as  host.  Sometimes,  however,  we 
have  the  archaic  box  with  three  locks,  so  frequent 
among  the  gilds;  and  in  such  cases  members  served 
in  rotation  as  "  keymasters,"  or,  as  we  should  now  say, 
trustees.  Thus  the  Edinburgh  Shoemakers  provided  that 
"  the  keymasters  shall  be  chosen  by  the  roll,  beginning  at 
the  top  for  the  first  keymaster,  and  at  the  middle  of  the 
roll  for  the  youngest  keymaster,  and  so  on  until  the  roll 
be  finished.  If  any  refuse  the  keymaster,  he  shall  pay 
one  shilling  and  sixpence  sterling."1  The  ancient  box  of 
the  Glasgow  Ropemakers'  Friendly  Society  (established 
1824),  elaborately  decorated  with  the  society's  "coat  of 
arms,"  was  kept  in  the  custody  of  the  president,  who  was 
elected  annually.2  Down  to  within  the  last  thirty  years 
the  custom  was  maintained  on  the  "  deacons'  choosing," 
or  annual  election  day,  of  solemnly  transporting  this  box 
through  the  streets  of  Glasgow  to  the  house  of  the  new 
president,  with  a  procession  of  ropespinners  headed  by  a 
piper,  the  ceremony  terminating  with  a  feast.  The  keeping 
of  accounts  and  the  writing  of  letters  was  a  later  develop- 
ment, and  when  a  clerk  or  secretary  was  needed,  he  had 
perforce  to  be  chosen  from  the  small  number  qualified  for 
the  work.  But  there  is  evidence  that  the  early  secre- 
taries served,  like  their  colleagues,  only  for  short  periods, 

society  ;  and  no  member  of  this  society  is  allowed  to  call  for  or  smoak  tobacco 
during  club  hours  in  the  club  room  ;  for  every  such  offence  he  is  to  forfeit  and 
pay  fourpence  to  the  stewards  for  the  use  of  the  box." — Articles  to  be  observed  by 
a  Society  of  Shipwrights,  or  the  True  British  Society,  all  Freemen  (Liverpool, 
1784),  Articles  8  and  9. 

1  Articles  of  the  Journeymen  Shoemakers  of  the  City  of  Edinburgh  (Edinburgh, 
!778) — a  society  established  in  1727. 

2  Articles  and  Regulations  of  the  Associated  Ropemakers1   Friendly  Society 
(Glasgow,  1836),  repeated  in  the  General  Laws  and  Regulations  of  the  Glasgow 
Ropemakers'  Trade  Protective  and  Friendly  Society  (Glasgow,  1 884).    The  members 
of  the  Glasgow  Typographical  Society  resolved,  in   1823,  "that  a  man  be  pro- 
vided on  election  nights  to  carry  the  box  from  the  residence  of  the  president  to  the 
place  of  meeting,  and  after  the  meeting  to   the   new   president's  house." — MS. 
Minutes  of  general  meeting,  Glasgow  Typographical  Society,  4th  October  1823. 


Primitive  Democracy  7 

and  occupied,  moreover,  a  position  very  subordinate  to  the 
president. 

Even  when  it  was  necessary  to  supplement  the  officers 
by  some  kind  of  committee,  so  far  were  these  infant  demo- 
cracies from  any  superstitious  worship  of  the  ballot-box, 
that,  although  we  know  of  no  case  of  actual  choice  by  lot,1 
the  committee-men  were  usually  taken,  as  in  the  case  of  the 
Steam-Engine  Makers'  Society,  "  in  rotation  as  their  names 
appear  on  the  books." 2  "A  fine  of  one  shilling,"  say  the 
rules  of  the  Southern  Amicable  Union  Society  of  Wool- 
staplers,  "  shall  be  levied  on  any  one  who  shall  refuse  to  serve 
on  the  committee  or  neglect  to  attend  its  stated  meetings, 
.  .  .  and  the  next  in  rotation  shall  be  called  in  his  stead."  3 
The  rules  of  the  Liverpool  Shipwrights  declared  "  that  the 
committee  shall  be  chosen  by  rotation  as  they  stand  in  the 
books  ;  and  any  member  refusing  to  serve  the  office  shall 
forfeit  ten  shillings  and  sixpence."4  As  late  as  1843  we 
find  the  very  old  Society  of  Curriers  resolving  that  for  this 
purpose  "  a  list  with  three  columns  be  drawn  up  of  the 
whole  of  the  members,  dividing  their  ages  as  near  as  possible 
in  the  following  manner :  the  elder,  the  middle-aged  and  the 
young ;  so  that  the  experience  of  the  elder  and  the  sound 

1  The  selection  of  officers  by  lot  was,  it  need  hardly  be  said,  frequent  in 
primitive  times.      It  is  interesting  to  find  the  practice  in  the  Swiss   "  Landes- 
gemeinden."     In  1640  the  "  Landesgemeinde  "  of  Glarus  began  to  choose  eight 
candidates  for  each  office,  who  then  drew  lots  among  themselves.     Fifty  years 
later  Schwyz  followed  this  example.      By  1793  the  "  Landesgemeinde  "  of  Glarus 
was  casting  lots  for  all  offices,  including  the  cantonal  secretaryship,  the  steward- 
ships of  dependent  territories,   etc.     The   winnei   often  sold  his  office  to   the 
highest  bidder.     The  practice  was  not  totally  abolished  until  1837,  and  old  men 
still  remember  the  passing  round  of  the  eight  balls,  each  wrapped  in  black  cloth, 
seven  being  silvern  and  the  eighth  gilt. — Les  Alpes  Suisses ;  fetudes  Historiques 
et  Nationals,  by  Eugene  Rambert  (Lausanne,  1889),  pp.  226,  276. 

2  Rules  of  the  Steam- Engine  Maker?  Society,  edition  of  1837. 

3  Rules  of  the  Southern  Amicable  Union  of  Woolstaplers  (London,  1837). 

4  Articles  to  be  observed  by  the  Association  of  the  Friendly  Union  of  Shipivrights, 
instituted  in  Liverpool  on  Tuesday,  \\th  November  1800  (Liverpool,  1800),  Rule 
19.     The  London  Sailmakers  resolved,  in  1836,  "that  from  this  evening  the 
calling  for  stewards  shall  begin  from  the  last  man  on  the  committee,  and  that 
from  and  after  the  last  steward  the  twelve  men  who  stand  in  rotation  on  the 
book  do  form  the  committee." — MS.  Minutes  of  general  meeting,  26th  September 
1836. 


8  Trade  Union  Structure 

judgment  of  the  middle-aged  will  make  up  for  any  deficiency 
on  the  part  of  the  young." l  In  some  cases,  indeed,  the 
members  of  the  committee  were  actually  chosen  by  the 
officers.  Thus  in  the  ancient  society  of  Journeymen  Paper- 
makers,  where  each  "  Grand  Division  "  had  its  committee  of 
eight  members,  it  was  provided  that  "  to  prevent  imposition 
part  of  the  committee  shall  be  changed  every  three  months, 
by  four  old  members  going  out  and  four  new  ones  coming 
in  ;  also  a  chairman  shall  be  chosen  to  keep  good  order, 
which  chairman,  with  the  clerk,  shall  nominate  the  four 
new  members  which  shall  succeed  the  four  old  ones."  2 

The  early  trade  club  was  thus  a  democracy  of  the  most 
rudimentary  type,  free  alike  from  permanently  differentiated 
officials,  executive  council,  or  representative  assembly. 
The  general  meeting  strove  itself  to  transact  all  the 
business,  and  grudgingly  delegated  any  of  its  functions 
either  to  officers  or  to  committees.  When  this  delegation 
could  no  longer  be  avoided,  the  expedients  of  rotation 
and  short  periods  of  service  were  used  "  to  prevent  im- 
position "  or  any  undue  influence  by  particular  members. 
In  this  earliest  type  of  Trade  Union  democracy  we  find,  in 
fact,  the  most  childlike  faith  not  only  that  "all  men  are 
equal,"  but  also  that  "  what  concerns  all  should  be  decided 
by  all." 

It  is  obvious  that  this  form  of  democracy  was  compatible 
only  with  the  smallest  possible  amount  of  business.  But  it 
was,  in  our  opinion,  not  so  much  the  growth  of  the  financial 
and  secretarial  transactions  of  the  unions,  as  the  exigencies  of 

1  MS.  Minutes  of  the  London  Society  of  Journeymen  Curriers,  January  1843. 

2  Rules  and  Articles  to  be  observed  by  the  Journeymen  Papermakers  throughout 
England '(1823),  Appendix  1 8  to  Report  on  Combination  Laws,  1825,  p.  56.    The 
only  Trade  Union  in  which  this  example  still  prevails  is  that  of  the  Flint  Glass 
Makers,  where  the  rules  until  lately  gave  the  secretary  "the  power  to  nominate 
a  central  committee   (open  to  the  objection  of  the   trade),  in  whose  hands  the 
executive  power  of  the  society  shall  be  vested  from  year  to  year." — Rules  and 
Regulations  of  the  National  Flint  Glass  Maker?  Sick  and  Friendly  Society  (Man- 
chester, 1890).     This  has  lately  been  modified,  in  so  far  that  seven  members  are 
now  elected,  the  central  secretary  nominating  four   "from  the  district  in  which 
he  resides,  but  open  to  the  objection  of  the  trade." — Rule  67  (Rules,  reprinted 
with  additions,  Manchester,  1893). 


Primitive  Democracy  9 

their  warfare  with  the  employers,  that  first  led  to  a  departure 
trom  this  simple  ideal.  The  legal  and  social  persecutions  to 
which  Trade  Unionists  were  subject,  at  any  rate  up  to  1824, 
made  secrecy  and  promptitude  absolutely  necessary  for  suc- 
cessful operations ;  and  accordingly  at  all  critical  times  we 
find  the  direction  of  affairs  passing  out  of  the  hands  of  the 
general  meeting  into  those  of  a  responsible,  if  not  a  repre- 
sentative, committee.  Thus  the  London  Tailors,  whose 
militant  combinations  between  1720  and  1834  repeatedly 
attracted  the  attention  of  Parliament,1  had  practically  two 
constitutions,  one  for  peace  and  one  for  war.  In  quiet  times, 
the  society  was  made  up  of  little  autonomous  general  meet- 
ings of  the  kind  described  above  at  the  thirty  "  houses  of 
call  "  in  London  and  Westminster.  The  organisation  for  war, 
as  set  forth  in  I  8 1  8  by  Francis  Place,  was  very  different : 
"  Each  house  of  call  has  a  deputy,  who  on  particular  occasions 
is  chosen  by  a  kind  of  tacit  consent,  frequently  without  its 
being  known  to  a  very  large  majority  who  is  chosen.  The 
deputies  form  a  committee,  and  they  again  choose,  in  a 
somewhat  similar  way,  a  very  small  committee,  in  whom, 
on  very  particular  occasions,  all  power  resides,  from  whom 
all  orders  proceed,  and  whose  commands  are  implicitly 
obeyed  ;  and  on  no  occasion  has  it  ever  been  known  that 
their  commands  have  exceeded  the  necessity  of  the  occasion, 
or  that  they  have  wandered  in  the  least  from  the  purpose 
for  which  it  was  understood  they  were  appointed.  So  perfect 
indeed  is  the  organisation,  and  so  well  has  it  been  carried 
into  effect,  that  no  complaint  has  ever  been  heard  ;  with  so 
much  simplicity  and  with  so  great  certainty  does  the  whole 
business  appear  to  be  conducted  that  the  great  body  of 
journeymen  rather  acquiesce  than  assist  in  any  way  in  it."  2 
Again,  the  protracted  legal  proceedings  of  the  Scottish  Hand- 

1  See    the    interesting    Select  Documents    illustrating  the  History  of   7*rade 
Unionism :  I.    The  Tailoring  Trade,  edited  by  F.  W.   Gallon  (London,  1896), 
being  one  of  the    "Studies"   published   by  the   London   School  of   Economics 
and  Political  Science. 

2  The  Gorgon,  No.  20,  3rd  October  1818,  reprinted  in  The  Tailoring  7radt 
by  F.  W.  Gallon,  pp.  153,  154. 


I0  Trade  Union  Structure 

loom  Weavers,  ending  in  the  great  struggle  when  30,000 
looms  from  Carlisle  to  Aberdeen  struck  on  a  single  day 
( i  oth  November  1812),  were  conducted  by  an  autocratic  com- 
mittee of  five,  sitting  in  Glasgow,  and  periodically  summon- 
ing from  all  the  districts  delegates  who  carried  back  to  their 
constituents  orders  which  were  implicitly  obeyed.1  Before 
the  repeal  of  the  Combination  Laws  in  1824,  the  employers 
in  all  the  organised  trades  complained  bitterly  of  these  "  self- 
appointed  "  committees,  and  made  repeated  attempts  to 
scatter  them  by  prosecutions  for  combination  or  conspiracy. 
To  this  constant  danger  of  prosecution  may  be  ascribed 
some  of  the  mystery  which  surrounds  the  actual  constitution 
of  these  tribunals  ;  but  their  appearance  on  the  scene  when- 
ever an  emergency  called  for  strong  action  was  a  necessary 
consequence  of  the  failure  of  the  clubs  to  provide  any  con- 
stitutional authority  of  a  representative  character. 

So  far  we  have  dealt  principally  with  trade  clubs  confined 
to  particular  towns  or  districts.  When,  in  any  trade,  these 
local  clubs  united  to  form  a  federal  union,  or  when  one  of 
them  enrolled  members  in  other  towns,  government  by  a 
general  meeting  of  "  the  trade,"  or  of  all  the  members,  be- 
came impracticable.2  Nowadays  some  kind  of  representa- 

1  Evidence    before    the    House    of   Commons   Committee   on   Artisans    and 
Machinery,  1824,  especially  that  of  Richmond. 

2  A  branch  of  a  national  union  is  still  governed  by  the  members  in  general 
meeting  assembled  ;  and  for  this  and  other  reasons,  it  is  customary  for  several 
separate  branches  to  be  established  in  large  towns  where  the  number  of  members 
becomes  greater  than  can  easily  be  accommodated  in  a  single  branch  meeting- 
place.      Such  branches  usually  send  delegates  to  a  district  committee,  which  thus 
becomes  the   real  governing  authority  of  the  town  or  district.      But  in  certain 
unions  the  idea  of  direct  government  by  an  aggregate  meeting  of  the  trade  still  so 
far  prevails  that,  even  in  so  large  a  centre  as  London,  resort  is  had  to  huge  mass 
meetings.     Thus  the  London  Society  of  Compositors  will  occasionally  summon 
its  ten  thousand  members  to  meet    in    council    to    decide,  in    an    excited  mass 
meeting,  the  question  of  peace  or  war  with  their  employers.     And  the  National 
Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives,  which  in  its  federal  constitution  adopts  a 
large  measure  of  representative  institutions,  still  retains  in  its  local  organisation 
the  aggregate  meeting  of  the  trade  as  the  supreme  governing  body  for  the  district. 
The  Shoemakers  of  London  or  Leicester  frequently  hold  meetings  at  which  the 
attendance  is  numbered  by  thousands,  with  results  that  are  occasionally  calamitous 
to  the  union.     Thus,  when   in  1891    the  men  of  a  certain   London   firm    had 
impetuously  left  their  work  contrary  to  the  agreement  made  by  the  union  with 


Primitive  Democracy  1 1 

tive  institutions  would  seem  to  have  been  inevitable  at  this 
stage.  But  it  is  significant  to  notice  how  slowly,  reluctantly 
and  incompletely  the  Trade  Unionists  have  incorporated  in 
their  constitutions  what  is  often  regarded  as  the  specifically 
Anglo- Saxon  form  of  democracy — the  elected  representative 
assembly,  appointing  and  controlling  a  standing  executive. 
Until  the  present  generation,  no  Trade  Union  had  ever 
formed  its  constitution  on  this  model.  It  is  true  that  in  the 
early  days  we  hear  of1  meetings  of  delegates  from  local 

the  employers,  their  branch  called  a  mass  meeting  of  the  whole  body  of  the 
London  members  (seven  thousand  attending),  which,  after  refusing  even  to  hear 
the  union  officials,  decided  to  support  the  recalcitrant  strikers,  with  the  result 
that  the  employers  "locked  out"  the  whole  trade.  (Monthly  Report  of  the 
National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives,  November  1891.)  In  1893  tne 
union  executive  found  it  necessary  to  summon  at  Leicester  a  special  delegate 
meeting  of  the  whole  society  to  sit  in  judgment  on  the  London  members  who 
had  decided,  at  a  mass  meeting,  to  withdraw  from  the  national  agreement  to 
submit  to  arbitration.  The  circular  calling  the  delegate  meeting  contains  a  vivid 
description  of  the  scene  at  this  mass  meeting:  "The  hall  was  well  filled,  and 
Mr.  Judge,  president  of  the  union,  took  the  chair.  From  the  outset  it  was  soon 
found  that  the  rowdy  element  intended  to  again  prevent  a  hearing,  and  thus  make 
it  impossible  for  our  views  to  be  laid  before  the  bulk  of  the  more  intelligent  and 
reasonable  members.  ...  If  democratic  unions  such  as  ours  are  to  have  the 
meetings  stopped  by  such  proceedings,  ...  if  the  members  refuse  to  hear,  and 
insult  by  cock-crowing  and  cat-calls  their  own  accredited  and  elected  executive, 
then  it  is  time  that  other  steps  be  taken."  The  delegate  meeting,  by  74  votes  to 
9,  severely  censured  the  London  members,  and  reversed  their  decision  (Circular  of 
Executive  Committee,  I4th  March  1893  :  Special  Report  of  the  Delegate 
Meeting  at  Leicester,  I7th  April  1893).  In  most  unions,  however,  experience 
has  shown  that  in  truth  "aggregate  meetings"  are  "aggravated  meetings,"  and 
has  led  to  their  abandonment  in  favor  of  district  committees  or  delegate  meetings. 
*  In  the  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  p.  46,  we  described  the  Hatters  as  hold- 
ing in  1772,  1775,  and  1777,  "congresses"  of  delegates  from  all  parts  of  the 
country.  Further  examination  of  the  evidence  (House  of  Commons  Journals, 
vol.  xxxvi.  ;  Place  MS.  27,799-68;  Committee  on  Artisans  and  Machinery) 
inclines  us  to  believe  that  these  "congresses,"  like  another  in  1816,  comprised 
only  delegates  from  the  various  workshops  in  London.  We  can  discover 
no  instance  during  the  eighteenth  century  of  a  Trade  Union  gathering  made  up 
of  delegates  from  the  local  clubs  throughout  the  country.  But  though  the  con- 
gresses of  the  Hatters  probably  represented  only  the  London  workmen,  their 
"  bye-laws  "  were  apparently  adopted  by  the  clubs  elsewhere,  and  came  thus  to 
be  of  national  scope.  Similar  instances  of  national  regulation  by  the  principal 
centre  of  a  trade  may  be  seen  in  the  "resolutions"  addressed  "to  the  Wool- 
staplers  of  England "  by  the  London  Society  of  Woolstaplers,  and  in  the 
"articles  to  be  observed  by  the  Journeymen  Papermakers  throughout  England," 
formulated  at  a  meeting  of  the  trade  at  large  held  at  Maidstone.  In  the  loose 
alliances  of  the  local  clubs  in  each  trade,  the  chief  trade  centre  often  acted,  in 
fact,  as  the  "governing  branch." 


i  2  Trade  Union  Structure 

clubs  to  adopt  or  amend  the  "  articles  "  of  their  association. 
A  "deputation"  from  nine  local  societies  of  Carpenters 
met  thus  in  London  in  1 8  2  7  to  form  the  Friendly  Society 
of  Operative  House  Carpenters  and  Joiners,  and  similar 
meetings  were  annually  held  to  revise  the  rules  and 
adjust  the  finances  of  this  federation.  It  would  have 
been  a  natural  development  for  such  a  representative 
congress  to  appoint  a  standing  committee  and  executive 
officers  to  act  on  behalf  of  the  whole  trade.  But  when 
between  1824  and  1840  the  great  national  societies  of 
that  generation  settled  down  into  their  constitutions,  the 
congress  of  elected  representatives  either  found  no  place  at 
all,  or  else  was  called  together  only  at  long  intervals  and  for 
strictly  limited  purposes.  In  no  case  do  we  see  it  acting 
as  a  permanent  supreme  assembly.  The  Trade  Union  met 
the  needs  of  expanding  democracy  by  some  remarkable 
experiments  in  constitution-making. 

The  first  step  in  the  transition  from  the  loose  alliance  of 
separate  local  clubs  into  a  national  organisation  was  the 
appointment  of  a  seat  of  government  or  "  governing  branch." 
The  members  residing  in  one  town  were  charged  with 
the  responsibility  of  conducting  the  current  business  of  the 
whole  society,  as  well  as  that  of  their  own  branch.  The 
branch  officers  and  the  branch  committee  of  this  town  accord- 
ingly became  the  central  authority.1  Here  again  the  leading 
idea  was  not  so  much  to  get  a  government  that  was  repre- 

1  In  some  of  the  more  elaborate  Trade  Union  constitutions  formulated  between 
1820  and  1834  we  find  a  hierarchy  of  authorities,  none  of  them  elected  by  the 
society  as  a  whole,  but  each  responsible  for  a  definite  part  of  the  common  admini- 
stration. Thus  The  Rules  and  Articles  to  be  observed  by  the  Journeymen  Paper- 
makers'^  1823  provide  "that  there  shall  be  five  Grand  Divisions  throughout 
England  where  all  money  shall  be  lodged,  that  when  wanted  may  be  sent  to 
any  part  where  emergency  may  require."  These  "Grand  Divisions"  were  the 
branches  in  the  five  principal  centres  of  the  trade,  each  being  given  jurisdiction 
over  all  the  mills  in  the  counties  round  about  it.  Above  them  all  stood  "  No.  I 
Grand  Division  "  (Maidstone),  which  was  empowered  to  determine  business  of 
too  serious  a  nature  to  be  left  to  any  other  Grand  Division.  This  geographical 
hierarchy  is  interesting  as  having  apparently  furnished  the  model  for  most  of  the 
constitutions  of  the  period,  notably  of  the  Owenite  societies  of  1833-1834,  includ- 
ing the  Builders'  Union  and  the  Grand  National  Consolidated  Trades  Union  itself. 


Primitive  Democracy  1 3 

sentative  of  the  society  as  to  make  each  section  take  its  turn 
at  the  privileges  and  burdens  of  administration.  The  seat 
of  government  was  accordingly  always  changed  at  short 
intervals,  often  by  rotation.  Thus  the  Steam-Engine  Makers' 
rules  of  1826  provide  that  "  the  central  branch  of  the  society 
shall  be  held  alternately  at  the  different  branches  of  this 
society,  according  as  they  stand  on  the  books,  commencing 
with  Branch  No.  I,  and  the  secretary  of  the  central  branch 
shall,  after  the  accounts  of  the  former  year  have  been  balanced, 
send  the  books  to  the  next  central  branch  of  the  society."  l 
In  other  cases  the  seat  of  government  was  periodically  deter- 
mined by  vote  of  the  whole  body  of  members,  who  appear 
usually  to  have  been  strongly  biassed  in  favor  of  shifting  it 
from  town  to  town.  The  reason  appears  in  this  statement 
by  one  of  the  lodges  of  the  Ironfounders :  "  What,  we  ask, 
has  been  the  history  of  nearly  every  trade  society  in  this 
respect  ?  Why,  that  when  any  branch  or  section  of  it  has 
possessed  the  governing  power  too  long,  it  has  become  care- 
less of  the  society's  interests,  tried  to  assume  irresponsible 
powers,  and  invariably  by  its  remissness  opened  wide  the 
doors  of  peculation,  jobbery,  and  fraud." 2 

The  institution  of  a  "  governing  branch  "  had  the  advantage 
of  being  the  cheapest  machinery  of  central  administration 
that  could  be  devised.  By  it  the  national  union  secured 
its  executive  committee,  at  no  greater  expense  than  a  small 
local  society.3  And  so  long  as  the  function  of  the  national 

The  same  geographical  hierarchy  was  a  feature  of  the  constitution  of  the  Southern 
Amicable  Society  of  Woolstaplers  until  the  last  revision  of  rules  in  1892.  In  only 
one  case  has  a  similar  hierarchy  survived.  The  United  Society  of  Brushmakers, 
established  in  the  eighteenth  century,  is  still  divided  into  geographical  divisions 
governed  by  the  six  head  towns,  with  London  as  the  centre  of  communication. 
The  branches  in  the  West  Riding,  for  instance,  are  governed  by  the  Leeds  com- 
mittee, and  when  in  1892  the  Sheffield  branch  had  a  strike,  this  was  managed  by 
the  secretary  of  the  Leeds  branch. 

1  Rule  19  ;  rules  of  1826  as  reprinted  in  the  Annual  Report  for  1837. 

2  Address  of  the  Bristol  branch  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders  to  the 
members  at  large  (in  Annual  Report  for  1849). 

3  Both  the  idea  of  rotation  of  office,  and  that  of  a  local  governing  branch,  can 
be  traced  to  the  network  of  village  sick-clubs  which  existed  all  over  England  in 
the  eighteenth  century.      In  1824  these  clubs  were  described  by  a  hostile  critic  as 
"under  the  management  of  the  ordinary  members  who  succeed  to  the  several  offices 


14  Trade  Union  Structure 

executive  was  confined  to  that  of  a  centre  of  communication 
between  practically  autonomous  local  branches,  no  alteration 
in  the  machinery  was  necessary.  The  duties  of  the  secretary, 
like  those  of  his  committee,  were  not  beyond  the  competence 
of  ordinary  artisans  working  at  their  trade  and  devoting  only 
their  evenings  to  their  official  business.  But  with  the  multi- 
plication of  branches  and  the  formation  of  a  central  fund,  the 
secretarial  work  of  a  national  union  presently  absorbed  the 
whole  time  of  a  single  officer,  to  whom,  therefore,  a  salary 
had  to  be  assigned.  As  the  salary  came  from  the  common 
fund,  the  right  of  appointment  passed,  without  question,  from 
the  branch  meeting  to  "the  voices"  of  the  whole  body  of 
members.  Thus  the  general  secretary  was  singled  out  for  a 
unique  position  :  alone  among  the  officers  of  the  union  he 
was  elected  by  the  whole  body  of  members.  Meanwhile  the 
supreme  authority  continued  to  be  "  the  voices."  Every  pro- 
position not  covered  by  the  original  "  articles,"  together  with 
all  questions  of  peace  and  war,  was  submitted  to  the  votes 
of  the  members.1  But  this  was  not  all.  Each  branch,  in 

in  rotation  ;  frequently  without  being  qualified  either  by  ability,  independence,  or 
impartiality  for  the  due  discharge  of  their  respective  offices  ;  or  under  the  control 
of  a  standing  committee,  composed  of  the  most  active  and  often  the  least  eligible 
members  residing  near  the  place  of  meeting." — The  Constitution  of  Friendly  Societies 
upon  Legal  and  Scientific  Principles,  by  Rev.  John  Thomas  Becher  (2nd  edition, 
London,  1824),  p.  50. 

Comparing  small  things  with  great,  we  may  say  that  the  British  Empire  is 
administered  by  a  "governing  branch."  The  business  common  to  the  Empire  as 
a  whole  is  transacted,  not  by  imperial  or  federal  officers,  but  by  those  of  one  part 
of  the  Empire,  the  United  Kingdom  of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland  ;  and  they  are 
supervised,  not  by  an  Imperial  Diet  or  Federal  Assembly,  but  by  the  domestic 
legislature  at  Westminster. 

1  The  very  ancient  United  Society  of  Brushmakers,  which  dates  from  the  early 
part  of  the  eighteenth  century,  retains  to  this  day  its  archaic  method  of  collecting 
"  the  voices."  In  London,  said  to  be  the  most  conservative  of  all  the  districts,  no 
alteration  of  rule  is  made  without  "  sending  round  the  box  "  as  of  yore.  In  the 
society's  ancient  iron  box  are  put  all  the  papers  relating  to  the  subject  under  dis- 
cussion, and  a  member  out  of  employment  is  deputed  to  carry  the  box  from  shop 
to  shop  until  it  has  travelled  "all  round  the  trade."  When  it  arrives  at  a  shop, 
all  the  men  cease  work  and  gather  round  ;  the  box  is  opened,  its  contents  are  read 
and  discussed,  and  the  shop  delegates  are  then  and  there  instructed  how  to  vote 
at  the  next  delegate  meeting.  The  box  is  then  refilled  and  sent  on  to  the  next 
shop.  Old  minutes  of  1829  show  that  this  custom  has  remained  unchanged,  down 
to  the  smallest  detail,  for,  at  any  rate,  a  couple  of  generations.  It  is  probably 
nearly  two  centuries  old. 


Primitive  Democracy  1 5 

general  meeting  assembled,  claimed  the  right  to  have  any 
proposition  whatsoever  submitted  to  the  vote  of  the  society 
as  a  whole.  And  thus  we  find,  in  almost  every  Trade  Union 
which  has  a  history  at  all,  a  most  instructive  series  of  experi- 
ments in  the  use,  misuse,  and  limitations  of  the  Referendum. 
Such  was  the  typical  Trade  Union  constitution  of  the 
last  generation.  In  a  few  cases  it  has  survived,  almost 
unchanged,  down  to  the  present  day,  just  as  its  pre- 
decessor, the  archaic  local  club  governed  by  the  general 
meeting,  still  finds  representatives  in  the  Trade  Union 
world.  But  wherever  an  old  Trade  Union  has  maintained 
its  vitality,  its  constitution  has  been  progressively  modified, 
whilst  the  most  powerful  of  the  modern  unions  have  been 
formed  on  a  different  pattern.  An  examination  of  this 
evolutionary  process  will  bring  home  to  us  the  transitional 
character  of  the  existing  constitutional  forms,  and  give  us 
valuable  hints  towards  the  solution,  in  a  larger  field,  of  the 
problem  of  uniting  efficient  administration  with  popular 
control. 

We  have  already  noted  that,  in  passing  from  a  local  to 
a  national  organisation,  the  Trade  Union  unwittingly  left 
behind  the  ideal  of  primitive  democracy.  The  setting  apart 
of  one  man  to  dcrthe  clerical  work  destroyed  the  possibility  of 
^equal  and^d^ntical  service  by  all  the  members,  and  laid  the 
rauji^kfion  of  a  separate  governing  class.  The  practice  of 
requiring  members  to  act  in  rotation  was  silently  abandoned. 
Once  chosen  for  his  post,  the  general  secretary  could  rely  with 
confidence,  unless  he  proved  himself  obviously  unfit  or  grossly 
incompetent,  on  being  annually  re-elected.  Spending  all 
day  at  office  work,  he  soon  acquired  a  professional  expert- 
ness  quite  out  of  the  reach  of  his  fellow -members  at 
the  bench  or  the  forge.  And  even  if  some  other  member 
possessed  natural  gifts  equal  or  superior  to  the  acquired 
skill  of  the  existing  officer,  there  was,  in  a  national  organisa- 
tion, no  opportunity  of  making  these  qualities  known.  The 
general  secretary,  on  the  other  hand,  was  always  adver- 
tising his  name  and  his  personality  to  the  thousands  of 


[  6  Trade  Union  Structure 

members  by  the  printed  circulars  and  financial  reports,  which 
became  the  only  link  between  the  scattered  branches,  and 
afforded  positive  evidence  of  his  competency  to  perform 
the  regular  work  of  the  office.  With  every  increase  in  the 
society's  membership,  with  every  extension  or  elaboration 
of  its  financial  system  or  trade  policy,  the  position  of  the 
salaried  official  became,  accordingly,  more  and  more  secure. 
The  general  secretaries  themselves  changed  with  the  develop- 
ment of  their  office.  The  work  could  no  longer  be 
efficiently  performed  by  an  ordinary  artisan,  and  some 
preliminary  office  training  became  almost  indispensable. 
The  Coalminers,  for  instance,  as  we  have  shown  in  our 
description  of  the  Trade  Union  world,  have  picked  their 
secretaries  to  a  large  extent  from  a  specially  trained  section, 
the  checkweigh-men.1  The  Cotton  Operatives  have  even 
adopted  a  system  of  competitive  examination  among  the 
candidates  for  their  staff  appointments.2  In  other  unions  any 
candidate  who  has  not  proved  his  capacity  for  office  work 
and  trade  negotiations  would  stand  at  a  serious  disadvantage 
in  the  election,  where  the  choice  is  coming  every  day  to  be 
confined  more  clearly  to  the  small  class  of  minor  officials. 
The  paramount  necessity  of  efficient  administration  has 
co-operated  with  this  pe.manence  in  producing  a  progressive 
differentiation  of  an  official  governing  class,  more  and  more 
marked  off  by  character,  training,  and  duties  from  the  bulk 
of  the  members.  The  annual  election  of  the  general 
secretary  by  a  popular  vote,  far  from  leading  to  frequent 
rotation  of  office  and  equal  service  by  all  the  members, 
has,  in  fact,  invariably  resulted  in  permanence  of  tenure 
exceeding  even  that  of  the  English  civil  servant.  It  is 
accordingly  interesting  to  notice  that,  in  the  later  rules 
of  some  of  the  most  influential  of  existing  unions,  the 
practical  permanence  of  the  official  staff  is  tacitly  recognised 
by  the  omission  of  all  provision  for  re-election.  Indeed,  the 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  p.  291. 

2  Ibid.  p.  294  ;  see  also  the  subsequent  chapter  on  "  The  Method  of  Collective 
Bargaining,"  where  a  specimen  examination  paper  is  reprinted. 


Primitive  Democracy  ij 

Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners  goes 
so  far  as  expressly  to  provide  in  its  rules  that  the  general 
secretary  "  shall  continue  in  office  so  long  as  he  gives  satis- 
faction." l 

While  everything  was  thus  tending  to  exalt  the  position 
of  the  salaried  official,  the  executive  committee,  under  whose 
direction  he  was  placed,  being  composed  of  men  working  at 
their  trade,  retained  its  essential  weakness.  Though  modi- 
fied in  unimportant  particulars,  it  continued  in  nearly  all  the 
old  societies  to  be  chosen  only  by  one  geographical  section 
of  the  members.  At  first  each  branch  served  in  rotation  as 
the  seat  of  government.  This  quickly  gave  way  to  a  system 
of  selecting  the  governing  branch  from  among  the  more 
important  centres  of  the  trade.  Moreover,  though  the  desire 
periodically  to  shift  the  seat  of  this  authority  long  manifested 
itself  and  still  lingers  in  some  trades,2  the  growth  of  an 
official  staff,  and  the  necessity  of  securing  accommodation 
on  some  durable  tenancy,  has  practically  made  the  head- 
quarters stationary,  even  if  the  change  has  not  been  ex- 
pressly recorded  in  the  rules.  Thus  the  Friendly  Society 
of  Ironfounders  has  retained  its  head  office  in  London  since 
1846,  and  the  Friendly  Society  of  Operative  Stonemasons 
since  1883.  The  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  which 
long  wandered  from  port  to  port,  has  remained  in  Newcastle 
since  1880;  and  finally  settled  the  question  in  1888  by 
building  itself  palatial  offices  on  a  freehold  site.3  Here  again 

1  Rule  12  in  the  editions  of  Rules  of  1891  and  1894. 

2  Notably  the  Plumbers  and  Irondressers.      In  1877  a  proposal  at  the  general 
council  of  the  Operative  Bricklayers'  Society  to  convert  the  executive  into  a  shift- 
ing one,  changing  the  headquarters  every  third  year,  was  only  defeated  by  a  cast- 
ing vote. — Operative  Bricklayers'  Society  Trade  Circular,  September  1877. 

3  Along  with  this  change  has  gone  the  differentiation  of  national  business  from 
that  of  the  branch.     The  committee  work  of  the  larger  societies  became  more  than 
could  be  undertaken,  in  addition  to  the  branch  management,  by  men  giving  only 
their  evenings.      We  find,  therefore,  the  central  executive  committee  becoming  a 
body  distinct  from  the  branch  committee,  sometimes  (as  in  the  United  Society  of 
Operative   Plumbers)  elected  by  the  same  constituents,  but  more  usually  by  the 
members  of  all  the  branches  within  a  convenient  radius  of  the  central  office.     Thus 
the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Carpenters  gives  the  election  to  the  members  within 
twelve  miles  of  the  head  office — that  is,  to  the  thirty-five  branches  in  and  near 
Manchester— and  the  Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders  to  the  six  branches  of  the 

VOL.  I  C 


1 8  Trade  Union  Structure 

the  deeply-rooted  desire  on  the  part  of  Trade  Union  demo- 
crats to  secure  to  each  section  an  equal  and  identical  share 
in  the  government  of  the  society  has  had  to  give  way  before 
the  necessity  of  obtaining  efficient  administration.  In  ceas- 
ing to  be  movable  the  executive  committee  lost  even  such 
moral  influence  over  the  general  secretary  as  was  conveyed 
by  an  express  and  recent  delegation  by  the  remainder  of  the 
society.  The  salaried  official,  elected  by  the  votes  of  all  the 
members,  could  in  fact  claim  to  possess  more  representative 
authority  than  a  committee  whose  functions  as  an  executive 
depended  merely  on  the  accident  of  the  society's  offices  being 
built  in  the  town  in  which  the  members  of  the  committee 
happened  to  be  working.  In  some  societies,  moreover, 
the  idea  of  Rotation  of  Office  so  far  survived  that  the 
committee  men  were  elected  for  a  short  term  and  disqualified 
for  re-election.  Such  inexperienced  and  casually  selected 
committees  of  tired  manual  workers,  meeting  only  in  the 
evening,  usually  found  themselves  incompetent  to  resist,  or 
even  to  criticise,  any  practical  proposal  that  might  be  brought 
forward  by  the  permanent  trained  professional  whom  they 
were  supposed  to  direct  and  control.1 

In  face  of  so  weak  an  executive  committee  the  most 
obvious  check  upon  the  predominant  power  of  the  salaried 
officials  was  the  elementary  device  of  a  written  constitution. 
The  ordinary  workman,  without  either  experience  or  imagina- 
tion, fondly  thought  that  the  executive  government  of  a 
great  national  organisation  could  be  reduced  to  a  mechanical 
obedience  to  printed  rules.  Hence  the  constant  elaboration 
of  the  rules  of  the  several  societies,  in  the  vain  endeavor  to 
leave  nothing  to  the  discretion  of  officers  or  committees.  It 
was  an  essential  part  of  the  faith  of  these  primitive  democrats 
that  the  difficult  and  detailed  work  of  drafting  and  amending 

London  district.  In  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  down  to  1897,  the 
twenty  lodges  in  the  Tyne  district,  each  in  rotation,  nominated  one  of  the  seven 
members  of  which  the  executive  committee  is  composed. 

1  The  only  organisation,  outside  the  Trade  Union  world,  in  which  the  execu- 
tive committee  and  the  seat  of  government  are  changed  annually,  is,  we  believe, 
the  Ancient  Order  of  Foresters,  the  worldwide  federal  friendly  society. 


Primitive  Democracy  19 

these  rules  should  not  be  delegated  to  any  particular  person 
or  persons,  but  should  be  undertaken  by  "  the  body  "  or  "  the 
trade  "  in  general  meeting  assembled.1 

When  a  society  spread  from  town  to  town,  and  a  meeting 
of  all  the  members  became  impracticable,  the  "  articles  "  were 
settled,  as  we  have  mentioned,  by  a  meeting  of  delegates,  and 
any  revision  was  undertaken  by  the  same  body.  Accordingly, 
we  find,  in  the  early  history  of  such  societies  as  the  Iron- 
founders,  Stonemasons,  Carpenters,  Coachmakers,  and  Steam- 
Engine  Makers,  frequent  assemblies  of  delegates  from  the 
different  branches,  charged  with  supplementing  or  revising 
the  somewhat  tentative  rules  upon  which  the  society  had 
been  based.  But  it  would  be  a  serious  misconception  to 
take  these  gatherings  for  "  parliaments,"  with  plenary  power 
to  determine  the  policy  to  be  pursued  by  the  society.  The 
delegates  came  together  only  for  specific  and  strictly  limited 
purposes.  Nor  were  even  these  purposes  left  to  be  dealt 
with  at  their  discretion.  In  all  cases  that  we  know  of  the 
delegates  were  bound  to  decide  according  to  the  votes 
already  taken  in  their  respective  branches.  In  many 
societies  the  delegate  was  merely  the  vehicle  by  which 
"  the  voices "  of  the  members  were  mechanically  con- 
veyed. Thus  the  Friendly  Society  of  Operative  Stone- 
masons, at  that  time  the  largest  and  most  powerful  Trade 

1  This  preference  of  Trade  Unionists  for  making  their  own  rules  will  remind 
the  political  student  that  "direct  legislation  by  the  people"  has  an  older  and 
wider  history  with  regard  to  the  framing  and  revising  of  constitutions  than  with 
regard  to  ordinary  legislation.  Thus,  already  in  1779  the  citizens  of  Massa- 
chusetts insisted  on  asserting,  by  popular  vote,  that  a  constitution  should  be 
framed,  and  equally  on  deciding  that  the  draft  prepared  should  be  adopted.  In 
1818  the  Connecticut  constitution  included  a  provision  that  any  particular 
amendment  to  it  might  be  submitted  to  the  popular  vote.  In  Europe  the  first 
constitution  to  be  submitted  to  the  same  ordeal  was  the  French  constitution  of 
r793>  which,  though  adopted  by  the  primary  assemblies,  never  came  into  force. 
The  practice  became  usual  with  regard  to  the  Swiss  cantonal  constitutions  after 
the  French  Revolution  of  1830,  St.  Gall  leading  the  way  in  July  1831.  See  the 
elaborate  treatise  of  Charles  Borgeaud  on  The  Adoption  and  Amendment  of 
Constitutions  (London,  1895);  Bryce's  The  American  Common-wealth  (London, 
1891);  and  Le  Referendum  en  Suisse  by  Simon  Deploige  (Brussels,  1892),  of 
which  an  English  translation  by  C.  P.  Trevelyan  and  Lilian  Tomn,  with 
additional  notes  and  appendices,  will  shortly  be  published  by  the  London 
School  of  Economics  and  Political  Science. 


2O  Trade  Union  Structure 

Union,  held  annual  delegate  meetings  between  1834  and 
1839  f°r  tne  s°le  PurPose  of  revising  its  rules.  How  limited 
was  the  power  of  this  assembly  may  be  judged  from  the 
following  extract  from  an  address  of  the  central  executive  : 
"  As  the  delegates  are  about  to  meet,  the  Grand  Committee 
submit  to  all  lodges  the  following  resolutions  in  reference  to 
the  conduct  of  delegates.  It  is  evident  that  the  duty  of 
delegates  is  to  vote  according  to  the  instructions  of  the  majority 
of  their  constituents,  therefore  they  ought  not  to  propose  any 
measure  unless  recommended  by  the  Lodges  or  Districts 
they  represent.  To  effect  this  we  propose  the  following 
resolutions  :  that  each  Lodge  shall  furnish  their  delegates 
with  written  instructions  how  to  vote  on  each  question  they 
have  taken  into  their  consideration,  and  that  no  delegate 
shall  vote  in  opposition  to  his  instructions,  and  when  it 
appears  by  examining  the  instructions  there  is  a  majority 
for  any  measure,  it  shall  be  passed  without  discussion."  *  The 
delegate  meeting  of  1838  agreed  with  this  view.  All  lodges 
were  to  send  resolutions  for  alterations  of  rules  two  months 
before  the  delegate  meeting ;  they  were  to  be  printed  in  the 
Fortnightly  Return,  and  discussed  by  each  lodge  ;  the  delegate 
was  then  to  be  instructed  as  to  the  sense  of  the  members  by 
a  majority  vote ;  and  only  if  there  was  no  decided  majority 
on  any  point  was  the  delegate  to  have  discretion  as  to  his 
vote.  But  even  this  restriction  did  not  satisfy  the  Stone- 
masons' idea  of  democracy.  In  1837  the  Liverpool  Lodge 
demanded  that  "  all  the  alterations  made  in  our  laws  at  the 
grand  delegate  meeting"  shall  be  communicated  to  all  the 
lodges  "  for  the  consideration  of  our  society  before  they  are 
printed."2  The  central  executive  mildly  deprecated  such  a 
course,  on  the  ground  that  the  amendment  and  passing  of 
the  laws  would  under  those  circumstances  take  up  the  whole 
time  of  the  society  until  the  next  delegate  meeting  came 
round.  The  request,  however,  was  taken  up  by  other 

1  Stonemason?  Fortnightly  Return,  May  1836  (the  circular  issued  fortnightly 
to  all  the  branches  by  the  executive  committee). 
a  Ibid.  May  1837. 


Primitive  Democracy  21 

branches,  and  by  1844  we  find  the  practice  established  of 
making  any  necessary  amendment  in  the  rules  by  merely 
submitting  the  proposal  in  the  Fortnightly  Return^  and  adding 
together  the  votes  taken  in  each  lodge  meeting.  A  similar 
change  took  place  in  such  other  great  societies  as  the  Iron- 
founders,  Steam-Engine  Makers,  and  Coachmakers.  The 
great  bulk  of  the  members  saw  no  advantage  in  incurring 
the  very  considerable  expense  of  paying  the  coach  fares  of 
delegates  to  a  central  town  and  maintaining  them  there  at 
the  rate  of  six  shillings  a  day,1  when  the  introduction  of 
penny  postage  made  possible  the  circulation  of  a  fortnightly 
or  monthly  circular,  through  the  medium  of  which  their 
votes  on  any  particular  proposition  could  be  quickly  and 
inexpensively  collected.  The  delegate  meeting  became,  in 
fact,  superseded  by  the  Referendum.2 

By  the  term  Referendum  the  modern  student  of  political 
institutions  understands  the  submission  to  the  votes  of  the 
whole  people  of  any  measure  deliberated  on  by  the  repre- 
sentative assembly.  Another  development  of  the  same  prin- 
ciple is  what  is  called  the  Initiative,  that  is  to  say,  the  right  of 
a  section  of  the  community  to  insist  on  its  proposals  being 
submitted  to  the  vote  of  the  whole  electorate.  As  a  repre- 
sentative assembly  formed  no  part  of  the  earlier  Trade  Union 
constitutions,  both  the  Referendum  and  the  Initiative  took 
with  them  the  crudest  shape.  Any  new  rule  or  amendment 
of  a  rule,  any  proposed  line  of  policy  or  particular  application 
of  it,  might  be  straightway  submitted  to  the  votes  of  all  the 

1  In  1838  a  large  majority  of  the  lodges  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Operative 
Stonemasons  voted  "that  on  all  measures  submitted  to  the  consideration  of  our 
Society,  the  number  of  members  be  taken  in  every  Lodge  for  and  against  such  a 
measure,  and  transmitted  through  the  district  Lodges  to  the  Seat  of  Government, 
and  in  place  of  the  number  of  Lodges,  the  majority  of  the  aggregate  members  to 
sanction  or  reject  any  measures." — Fortnightly  Return,  ipth  January  1838. 

2  It  is  interesting  to  find  that  in  at  least  one  Trade  Union  the  introduction  of 
the  Referendum  is  directly  ascribed  to  the  circulation  in  England  between  1850  and 

1860  of  translations  of  pamphlets  by  Rittinghausen  and  Victor  Considerant.      It  is 
stated  in  the  Typographical  Circular  for  March  1889,  that  John  Melson,  a  Liver- 
pool printer,  got  the  idea  of  "Direct  Legislation  by  the  People"  from  these 
pamphlets,  and  urged  its  adoption  on  the  union,  at  first  unsuccessfully,  but  at  the 

1861  delegate  meeting  with  the  result  that  the  Referendum  was  adopted  as  the 
future  method  of  legislation. 


22  Trade  Union  Structure 

members.  Nor  was  this  practice  of  consulting  the  members 
confined  to  the  central  executive.  Any  branch  might  equally 
have  any  proposition  put  to  the  vote  through  the  medium  of 
the  society's  official  circular.  And  however  imperfectly  the 
question  was  framed,  however  inconsistent  the  result  might 
be  with  the  society's  rules  and  past  practice,  the  answer  re- 
turned by  the  members'  votes  was  final  and  instantly  operative. 
Those  who  believe  that  pure  democracy  implies  the  direct 
decision,  by  the  mass  of  the  people,  of  every  question  as  it 
arises,  will  find  this  ideal  realised  without  check  or  limit  in  the 
history  of  the  larger  Trade  Unions  between  1834  and  1870. 
The  result  was  significant  and  full  of  political  instruction. 
Whenever  the  union  was  enjoying  a  vigorous  life  we  find,  to 
begin  with,  a  wild  rush  of  propositions.  Every  active  branch 
had  some  new  rule  to  suggest,  and  every  issue  of  the  official 
circular  was  filled  with  crude  and  often  inconsistent  projects 
of  amendment.  The  executive  committee  of  the  United 
Kingdom  Society  of  Coachmakers,  for  instance,  had  to  put 
no  fewer  than  forty-four  propositions  simultaneously  to  the 
vote  in  a  single  circular.1  It  is  difficult  to  convey  any 
adequate  idea  of  the  variety  and,  in  some  cases,  the  absurdity 
of  these  propositions.  To  take  only  those  recorded  in  the 
annals  of  the  Stonemasons  between  1838  and  1839;  we 
have  one  branch  proposing  that  the  whole  society  should  go 
in  for  payment  by  the  hour,  and  another  that  the  post  of 
general  secretary  should  be  put  up  to  tender,  "  the  cheapest 
to  be  considered  the  person  elected  to  that  important 
office."  2  We  have  a  delegate  meeting  referring  to  a  vote  of 
the  members  the  momentous  question  whether  the  central 
executive  should  be  allowed  "  a  cup  of  ale  each  per  night," 
and  the  central  executive  taking  a  vote  as  to  whether  all  the 
Irish  branches  should  not  have  Home  Rule  forced  upon 
them.  The  members,  under  fear  of  the  coming  Parliamentary 

1  Quarterly  Report,  June  1860. 

2  The  sale  of  public  offices  by  auction  to  the  highest  bidder  was  a  frequent 
incident  in  the   Swiss  "  Landesgemeinden "   of  the   seventeenth  century.      See 
Eugene  Rambert's  Les  Alpes  Suisses  ;  Etudes  Historiques  et  Nationales,  p.  225. 


Primitive  Democracy  23 

inquiry,  vote  the  abolition  of  all  "  regalia,  initiation,  and 
pass-words,"  but  reject  the  proposition  of  the  Newcastle 
Lodge  for  reducing  the  hours  of  labor  "  as  the  only  method 
of  striking  at  the  root  of  all  our  grievances."  The  central 
executive  is  driven  to  protest  against  "  the  continual  state  of 
agitation  in  which  the  society  has  been  kept  for  the  last  ten 
months  by  the  numerous  resolutions  and  amendments  to 
laws,  the  tendency  of  which  can  only  be  to  bring  the  laws 
and  the  society  into  disrespect."  l  As  other  unions  come  to 
the  same  stage  in  development,  we  find  a  similar  result. 
"  It  appears  evident,"  complains  the  executive  committee  of 
the  Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders,  "  that  we  have  got  into 
a  regular  proposition  mania.  One  branch  will  make  propo- 
sitions simply  because  another  does  ;  hence  the  absurd  and 
ridiculous  propositions  that  are  made."  2  The  system  worked 
most  disastrously  in  connection  with  the  rates  of  contributions 
and  benefits.  It  is  not  surprising  that  the  majority  of  work- 
men should  have  been  unable  to  appreciate  the  need  for 
expert  advice  on  these  points,  or  that  they  should  have 
disregarded  all  actuarial  considerations.  Accordingly,  we 
find  the  members  always  reluctant  to  believe  that  the  rate 
of  contribution  must  be  raised,  and  generally  prone  to  listen 
to  any  proposal  for  extending  the  benefits — a  popular  bias 
which  led  many  societies  into  bankruptcy.  Still  more  dis- 
integrating in  its  tendency  was  the  disposition  to  appeal  to 
the  votes  of  the  members  against  the  executive  decision  that 
particular  individuals  were  ineligible  for  certain  benefits.  In 
the  United  Kingdom  Society  of  Coachmakers,  for  instance, 
we  find  the  executive  bitterly  complaining  that  it  is  of  no 
use  for  them  to  obey  the  rules,  and  rigidly  to  refuse  accident 
benefit  to  men  who  are  suffering  simply  from  illness  ;  as  in 
almost  every  case  the  claimant's  appeal  to  the  members, 
backed  by  eloquent  circulars  from  his  friends,  has  resulted 
in  the  decision  being  overruled.8  The  Friendly  Society  of 


1  Fortnightly  Return,  July  1838. 

*  Ironfounders1  Monthly  Report,  April  1855. 


United  Kingdom  Society  of  Coachmakers'  Qtwrterly  Report,  September  1859. 


24  Trade  Union  Structure 

Ironfounders  took  no  fewer  than  nineteen  votes  in  a  single 
year,  nearly  all  on  details  of  benefit  administration.1  And 
the  executive  of  the  Stonemasons  had  early  occasion  to 
protest  against  the  growing  practice  under  which  branches, 
preparatory  to  taking  a  vote,  sent  circulars  throughout  the 
society  in  support  of  their  claims  to  the  redress  of  what  they 
deemed  to  be  personal  grievances.2 

The  disadvantages  of  a  free  resort  to  the  Referendum 
soon  became  obvious  to  thoughtful  Trade  Unionists.  It  stands 
to  the  credit  of  the  majority  of  the  members  that  wild  and 
absurd  propositions  were  almost  uniformly  rejected  ;  and  in 
man)/  societies  a  similar  fate  became  customary  in  case  of 
any  proposition  that  did  not  emanate  from  the  responsible 
executive.8  The  practical  abandonment  of  the  Initiative 
ensued.  Branches  got  tired  of  sending  up  proposals  which 
uniformly  met  with  defeat.  But  the  right  of  the  whole 
body  of  members  themselves  to  decide  every  question  as 
it  arose  was  too  much  bound  up  with  their  idea  of 
democracy  to  permit  of  its  being  directly  abrogated,  or  even 
expressly  criticised.  Where  the  practice  did  not  die  out 
from  sheer  weariness,  it  was  quietly  got  rid  of  in  other  ways. 
In  one  society  after  another  the  central  executive  and  the 
general  secretary — the  men  who  were  in  actual  contact  with 
the  problems  of  administration — silently  threw  their  influence 
against  the  practice  of  appealing  to  the  members'  vote.  Thus 
the  executive  committee  of  the  United  Kingdom  Society  of 
Coachmakers  made  a  firm  stand  against  the  members'  habit 
of  overruling  its  decision  in  the  grant  of  benefits  under  the 
rules.  The  executive  claimed  the  sole  right  to  decide  who 
was  eligible  under  the  rules,  and  refused  to  allow  discontented 
claimants  to  appeal  through  the  official  circular.  This  caused 
great  and  recurring  discontent ;  but  the  executive  committee 

1  Report  for  1 869. 

2  Fortnightly  Return,  1 8th  January  1849. 

3  The  political  student  will  be  reminded  of  the  very  small  number  of  cases 
in    which   the  Initiative   in  Switzerland   has  led    to  actual   legislation,   even   in 
cantons,  such  as  Zurich,  where  it  has  been  in  operation  for  over  twenty  years. 
See  Stiissi,  Referendum  und  Initiative  ini  Canton  Zurich. 


Primitive  Democracy  25 

held  firmly  to  their  position  and  eventually  maintained  it. 
When  thirteen  branches  of  the  Operative  Bricklayers'  Society 
proposed  in  1868  that  the  age  for  superannuation  should 
be  lowered  and  the  office  expenses  curtailed,  the  general 
secretary  bluntly  refused  to  submit  such  inexpedient  proposals 
to  the  members'  vote,  on  the  excuse  that  the  question  could 
be  dealt  with  at  the  next  delegate  meeting.1  The  next  step 
was  to  restrict  the  number  of  opportunities  for  appeals  on 
any  questions  whatsoever.  The  Coachmakers'  executive 
announced  that,  in  future,  propositions  would  be  put  to  the 
vote  only  in  the  annual  report,  instead  of  quarterly  as  hereto- 
fore, and  this  restriction  was  a  few  years  later  embodied  in 
the  rules.2  Even  more  effectual  was  the  enactment  of  a  rule 
throwing  the  expense  of  taking  a  vote  upon  the  branch  which 
had  initiated  it,  in  case  the  verdict  of  the  society  proved  to 
be  against  the  proposition.3  Another  device  was  to  seize  the 
occasion  of  a  systematic  revision  of  rules  to  declare  that  no 
proposition  for  their  alteration  was  to  be  entertained  for  a 
specified  period  :  one  year,  said  the  General  Union  of  Car- 
penters in  1863  ;  three  years,  declared  the  Bookbinders' 
Consolidated  Union  in  1869,  and  the  Friendly  Society  of 
Operative  Stonemasons  in  1878  ;  ten  years,  ordained  the 
Operative  Bricklayers'  Society  in  iSSp.4  Finally,  we  have 
the  Referendum  abolished  altogether,  as  regards  the  making 
or  alteration  of  rules.  In  1866  the  delegate  meeting  of  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Carpenters  decided  that  the  execu- 
tive should  "  not  take  the  votes  of  the  members  concerning 
any  alteration  or  addition  to  rules,  unless  in  cases  of  great 
emergency,  and  then  only  on  the  authority  of  the  General 
Council."5  In  1878  the  Stonemasons  themselves,  who  forty 
years  previously  had  been  enthusiastic  in  their  passion  for 
voting  on  every  question  whatsoever,  accepted  a  rule 

1  Monthly  Circular,  April  1868. 

8  Quarterly  Report^  November  1854;  Rules  of  1857. 

3  Rules   of  the  Associated  Blacksmiths    Society  (Glasgow,  1892),  and  many 
others. 

4  Monthly  Report,  October  1889. 
6  Monthly  Circular,  April  1866. 


26  Trade  Union  Structiire 

which  confined  the  work  of  revision   to  a  specially  elected 
committee. 

Thus  we  see  that  half  a  century  of  practical  experience 
of  the  Initiative  and  the  Referendum  has  led,  not  to  its 
extension,  but  to  an  ever  stricter  limitation  of  its  application. 
The  attempt  to  secure  the  participation  of  every  member  in 
the  management  of  his  society  was  found  to  lead  to  in- 
stability in  legislation,  dangerous  unsoundness  of  finance,  and 
general  weakness  of  administration.  The  result  was  the  early 
abandonment  of  the  Initiative,  either  by  express  rule  or  through 
the  persistent  influence  of  the  executive.  This  produced  a 
further  shifting  of  the  balance  of  power  in  Trade  Union  con- 
stitutions. When  the  right  of  putting  questions  to  the  vote 
came  practically  to  be  confined  to  the  executive,  the  Referen- 
dum ceased  to  provide  the  members  with  any  effective  control. 
If  the  executive  could  choose  the  issues  to  be  submitted^the 
occasion  on  which  the  question  should  be  put,  and  the  form  in 
which  it  should  be  couched,  the  Referendum,  far  from  supply- 
ing any  counterpoise  to  the  executive,  was  soon  found  to  be 
an  immense  addition  to  its  power.  Any  change  which  the 
executive  desired  could  be  stated  in  the  most  plausible 
terms  and  supported  by  convincing  arguments,  which  almost 
invariably  secured  its  adoption  by  a  large  majority.  Any 
executive  resolution  could,  when  occasion  required,  thus  be 
given  the  powerful  moral  backing  of  a  plebiscitary  vote.1 
The  reliance  of  Trade  Union  democrats  on  the  Referendum 
resulted,  in  fact,  in  the  virtual  exclusion  of  the  general  body 
of  members  from  all  real  share  in  the  government.  And 

1  Mr.  Lecky  points  out  (Democracy  and  Liberty ',  vol.  i.  pp.  12,  31,  32)  how, 
in  France,  "successive  Governments  soon  learned  how  easily  a  plebiscite  vote 
could  be  secured  and  directed  by  a  strong  executive,  and  how  useful  it  might 
become  to  screen  or  justify  usurpation.  The  Constitution  of  1795,  which  founded 
the  power  of  the  Directors  ;  the  Constitution  of  1799,  which  placed  the  executive 
power  in  the  hands  of  three  Consuls  elected  for  ten  years  ;  the  Constitution  of  1802, 
which  made  Buonaparte  Consul  for  life,  and  again  remodelled  the  electoral  system  ; 
the  Empire,  which  was  established  in  1804,  and  the  additional  Act  of  the  Con- 
stitution promulgated  by  Napoleon  in  1815,  were  all  submitted  to  a  direct  popular 
vote."  The  government  of  Napoleon  III.,  from  1852  to  1870,  was  ratified  by 
four  separate  plebiscites.  See  also  Laferriere,  Constitutions  de  la  France  depuh 
If8<);  Jules  Clere,  Histoire  du  Souffrage  Universel. 


Primitive  Democracy  27 

when  we  remember  the  practical  subordination  of  the 
executive  committee  to  its  salaried  permanent  officer,  we 
shall  easily  understand  that  the  ultimate  effect  of  such  a 
Referendum  as  we  have  described  was  a  further  strengthen- 
ing of  the  influence  of  the  general  secretary,  who  drafted  the 
propositions,  wrote  the  arguments  in  support  of  them,  and 
edited  the  official  circular  which  formed  the  only  means 
of  communication  with  the  members. 

We  see,  therefore,  that  almost  every  influence  in  the 
Trade  Union  organisation  has  tended  to  magnify  and  con- 
solidate the  power  of  the  general  secretary.  If  democracy 
could  furnish  no  other  expedient  of  popular  control  than  the 
mass  meeting,  the  annual  election  of  public  officers,  the 
Initiative  and  the  Referendum,  Trade  Union  history  makes 
it  quite  clear  that  the  jriere_rjr£,ssure  of  aHministrative  needs 
would  inevitably  result  in  the  general  body  of  citizens  losing 
all  effective  control  over  the  government.  It  would  not  be 
difficult  to  point  to  influential  Trade  Unions  at  the  present 
day  which,  possessing  only  a  single  permanent  official,  have 
not  progressed  beyond  the  stage  of  what  is  virtually  a 
personal  dictatorship.  But  it  so  happens  that  the  very 
development  of  the  union  and  its  business  which  tends,  as 
we  have  seen,  to  increase  the  influence  of  the  general 
secretary,  calls  into  existence  a  new  check  upon  his  personal 
authority.  If  we  examine  the  constitution  of  a  bank  or  joint 
stock  company,  or  any  other  organisation  not  formed  by  the 
working  class,  we  shall  find  it  almost  invariably  the  rule  that 
the  chief  executive  officers  are  appointed,  not  by  the  members 
at  large,  but  by  the  governing  committee,  and  that  these 
officers  are  allowed  a  free  hand,  if  not  absolute  power,  in  the 
choice  and  dismissal  of  their  subordinates.  Any  other  plan, 
it  is  contended,  would  seriously  detract  from  the  efficient 
working  of  the  organisation.  Had  the  Trade  Unions 
adopted  this  course,  the  general  secretary  would  have 
been  absolutely  supreme.  But  working-class  organisations 
in  England  have,  almost  without  exception,  tenaciously 
clung  to  the  direct  election  of  all  officers  by  the  general 


28  Trade  Union  Structure 

body  of  members.  Whether  the  post  to  be  filled  be 
that  of  assistant  secretary  at  the  head  office  or  district 
delegate  to  act  for  one  part  of  the  country,  the  members 
have  jealously  retained  the  appointment  in  their  own  hands. 
In  the  larger  trade  societies  of  the  present  day  the  general 
secretary  finds  himself,  therefore,  at  the  head,  not  of  a  staff  of 
docile  subordinates  who  owe  office  and  promotion  to  himself, 
but  of  a  number  of  separately  elected  functionaries,  each 
holding  his  appointment  directly  from  the  members  at  large.! 
Any  attempt  at  a  personal  dictatorship  is  thus  quickly 
checked.  There  is  more  danger  that  friction  and  personal 
jealousies  may  unduly  weaken  the  administration.  But  the 
usual  outcome  is  the  close  union  of  all  the  salaried  officials 
to  conduct  the  business  of  the  society  in  the  way  they  think 
best.  Instead  of  a  personal  dictatorship,  we  have,  therefore, 
a  closely  combined  and  practically  irresistible  bureaucracy. 

Under  a  constitution  of  this  type  the  Trade  Union 
may  attain  a  high  degree  of  efficiency.  The  United  Society 
of  Boilermakers  and  Ironshipbuilders  (established  1832; 
membership  in  December  1896,  40,776)  is,  for  instance, 
admittedly  one  of  the  most  powerful  and  best  conducted  of 
English  trade  societies.  For  the  last  twenty  years  its  career, 
alike  in  good  times  and  bad,  has  been  one  of  continuous 
prosperity.  For  many  years  past  it  has  dominated  all  the 
shipbuilding  ports,  and  it  now  includes  practically  every 
ironshipbuilder  in  the  United  Kingdom.  As  an  insurance 
company  it  has  succeeded  in  paying,  even  in  the  worst  years 
of  an  industry  subject  to  the  most  acute  depressions,  benefits 
of  an  unusually  elaborate  and  generous  character.  Notwith- 
standing these  liberal  benefits,  it  has  built  up  a  reserve  fund 
of  no  less  than  £175,560.  Nor  has  this  prosperity  been 

1  Even  the  office  staff  has  been,  until  quite  recently,  invariably  recruited  by 
the  members  from  the  members  ;  and  only  in  a  few  unions  has  it  begun  to  be 
realised  that  a  shorthand  clerk  or  trained  bookkeeper,  chosen  by  the  general 
secretary  or  the  executive  committee,  can  probably  render  better  service  at  the 
desk  than  the  most  eligible  workman  trained  to  manual  labor.  The  Operative 
Bricklayers'  Society,  however,  lately  allowed  their  executive  committee  to  appoint 
a  shorthand  clerk. 


Primitive  Democracy  29 

attained  by  any  neglect  of  the  militant  side  of  Trade 
Unionism.  The  society,  on  the  contrary,  has  the  reputa- 
tion of  exercising  stricter  control  over  the  conditions  of  its 
members'  work  than  any  other  union.  In  no  trade,  for 
instance,  do  we  find  a  stricter  and  more  universally  enforced 
limitation  of  apprentices,  or  a  more  rigid  refusal  to  work 
with  non-unionists.  And,  as  we  have  elsewhere  described, 
no  society  has  more  successfully  concluded  and  enforced 
elaborate  national  agreements  applicable  to  every  port  in  the 
kingdom.  Moreover,  this  vigorous  and  successful  trade 
policy  has  been  consistent  with  a  marked  abstention  from 
strikes — a  fact  due  not  only  to  the  financial  strength  and 
perfect  combination  of  the  society,  but  also  to  the  implicit 
obedience  enforced  upon  its  members,  and  the  ample  dis- 
ciplinary power  vested  in  and  exercised  by  the  central 
executive.1 

The  efficiency  and  influence  of  this  remarkable  union  is, 
no  doubt,  largely  due  to  the  advantageous  strategic  position 
which  has  resulted  from  the  extraordinary  expansion  of  iron- 
shipbuilding.  It  is  interesting,  however,  to  notice  what  a 
perfect  example  it  affords  of  a  constitution  retaining  all  the 
features  of  the  crudest  democracy,  but  becoming,  in  actual 
practice,  a  bureaucracy  in  which  effective  popular  control  has 
sunk  to  a  minimum.  The  formal  constitution  of  the  Boiler- 
makers' Society  still  includes  all  the  typical  features  of  the 
early  Trade  Union.  The  executive  government  of  this  great 
national  society  is  vested  in  a  constantly  changing  committee, 
the  members  of  which,  elected  by  a  single  district,  serve  only 
for  twelve  months,  and  are  then  ineligible  for  re-election 
during  three  years.  All  the  salaried  officials  are  separately 
elected  by  the  whole  body  of  members,  and  hold  their  posts 
only  for  a  prescribed  term  of  two  to  five  years.  Though 
provision  is  made  for  a  delegate  meeting  in  case  the  society 
desires  it,  all  the  rules,  including  the  rates  of  contribution  and 

1  See  the  enthusiastic  description  of  this  organisation  in  Ztim  Socialen  Frieden 
(Leipzig,  1890),  2  vols.,  by  Dr.  G.  von  Schulze-Gaevernitz,  translated  as  Social 
Peace  (London,  1893),  pp.  239-243. 


30  Trade  Union  Structure 

benefit,  can  be  altered  by  aggregate  vote ;  and  even  if  a 
delegate  meeting  assembles,  its  amendments  have  to  be 
submitted  to  the  votes  of  the  branches  in  mass  meeting. 
Any  branch,  moreover,  may  insist  that  any  proposition 
whatsoever  shall  be  submitted  to  this  same  aggregate  vote. 
The  society,  in  short,  still  retains  the  form  of  a  Trade  Union 
democracy  of  the  crudest  type. 

But  although  the  executive  committee,  the  branch 
meeting  and  the  Referendum  occupy  the  main  body  of  the 
society's  rules,  the  whole  policy  has  long  been  directed  and 
the  whole  administration  conducted  exclusively  by  an  infor- 
mal cabinet  of  permanent  officials  which  is  unknown  to  the 
printed  constitution.  Twenty  years  ago  the  society  had  the 
good  fortune  to  elect  as  general  secretary,  Mr.  Robert  Knight, 
a  man  of  remarkable  ability  and  strength  of  character,  who 
has  remained  the  permanent  premier  of  this  little  kingdom. 
During  his  long  reign,  there  has  grown  up  around  him  a  staff 
of  younger  officials,  who,  though  severally  elected  on  their 
individual  merits,  have  been  in  no  way  able  to  compete  with 
their  chief  for  the  members'  allegiance.  These  district  dele- 
gates are  nominally  elected  only  for  a  term  of  two  years,  just 
as  the  general  secretary  himself  is  elected  only  for  a  term  of 
five  years.  But,  for  the  reasons  we  have  given  elsewhere,  all 
these  officials  enjoy  a  permanence  of  tenure  practically  equal 
to  that  of  a  judge.  Mr.  Knight's  unquestioned  superiority  in 
Trade  Union  statesmanship,  together  with  the  invariable 
support  of  the  executive  committee,  have  enabled  him  to 
construct,  out  of  the  nominally  independent  district  delegates, 
a  virtual  cabinet,  alternately  serving  as  councillors  on  high 
issues  of  policy  and  as  ministers  carrying  out  in  their  own 
spheres  that  which  they  have  in  council  decided.  From  the 
written  constitution  of  the  society,  we  should  suppose  that 
it  was  from  the  evening  meetings  of  the  little  Newcastle 
committee  of  working  platers  and  rivetters  that  emanated  all 
those  national  treaties  and  elaborate  collective  bargains  with 
the  associated  employers  that  have  excited  the  admiration  of 
economic  students.  But  its  unrepresentative  character,  the 


Primitive  Democracy  3 1 

short  term  of  service  of  its  members  and  the  practical  rota- 
tion of  office  make  it  impossible  for  the  constantly  shifting 
executive  committee  to  exercise  any  effective  influence  over 
even  the  ordinary  routine  business  of  so  large  a  society.  The 
complicated  negotiations  involved  in  national  agreements  are 
absolutely  beyond  its  grasp.  What  actually  happens  is  that, 
in  any  high  issue  of  policy,  Mr.  Knight  summons  his  district 
delegates  to  meet  him  in  council  at  London  or  Manchester, 
to  concert,  and  even  to  conduct,  with  him  the  weighty 
negotiations  which  the  Newcastle  executive  formally  endorses. 
And  although  the  actual  administration  of  the  benefits  is 
conducted  by  the  branch  committees,  the  absolute  centralisa- 
tion of  funds  and  the  supreme  disciplinary  power  vested  in 
the  executive  committee  make  that  committee,  or  rather  the 
general  secretary,  as  dominant  in  matters  of  finance  as  in 
trade  policy.  The  only  real  opportunity  for  an  effective 
expression  of  the  popular  will  comes  to  be  the  submission  of 
questions  to  the  aggregate  vote  of  the  branches  in  mass 
meeting  assembled.  It  is  needless  to  point  out  that  a 
Referendum  of  this  kind,  submitted  through  the  official 
circular  in  whatsoever  terms  the  general  secretary  may 
choose,  and  backed  by  the  influence  of  the  permanent  staff 
in  every  district,  comes  to  be  only  a  way  of  impressing  the 
official  view  on  the  whole  body  of  members.  In  effect 
the  general  secretary  and  his  informal  cabinet  were,  until  the 
change  of  1895,  absolutely  supreme.1 

In  the  case  of  the  Boilermakers,  government  by  an 
informal  cabinet  of  salaried  officials  has,  up  to  the  present 
time,  been  highly  successful.  It  is,  however,  obvious  that  a 
less  competent  statesman  than  Mr.  Knight  would  find  great 
difficulty  in  welding  into  a  united  cabinet  a  body  of  district 

1  In  1895,  aftgr  tnis  chapter  was  written,  the  constitution  was  changed,  owing 
to  the  growing  feeling  of  the  members  in  London  and  some  other  towns,  that  their 
bureaucracy  was,  under  the  old  forms,  completely  beyond  their  control.  By  the 
new  rules  the  government  is  vested  in  a  representative  executive  of  seven  salaried 
members,  elected  by  the  seven  electoral  districts  into  which  the  whole  society 
is  divided,  for  a  term  of  three  years,  one-third  retiring  annually. — Rules  of  the, 
United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  etc.  (Newcastle,  1895).  It  is  as  yet  too  soon  to 
comment  on  the  effect  of  this  change,  which  only  came  into  operation  in  1897. 


32  Trade  Union  Structure 

officers  separately  responsible  to  the  whole  society,  and 
nominally  subject  only  to  their  several  district  committees. 
Under  these  circumstances  any  personal  friction  or  disloyalty 
might  easily  paralyse  the  whole  trade  policy,  upon  which  the 
prosperity  of  the  society  depends.  Moreover,  though  under 
Mr.  Knight's  upright  and  able  government  the  lack  of  any 
supervising  authority  has  not  been  felt,  it  cannot  but  be 
regarded  as  a  defect  that  the  constitution  provides  no  prac- 
tical control  over  a  corrupt,  negligent,  or  incompetent  general 
secretary.  The  only  persons  in  the  position  to  criticise 
effectually  the  administration  of  the  society  are  the  salaried 
officials  themselves,  who  would  naturally  be  indisposed  to 
risk  their  offices  by  appealing,  against  their  official  superior, 
to  the  uncertain  arbitrament  of  an  aggregate  vote.  Finally, 
this  constitution,  with  all  its  parade  of  democratic  form, 
secures  in  reality  to  the  ordinary  plater  or  rivetter  little  if 
any  active  participation  in  the  central  administration  of 
his  Trade  Union  ;  no  real  opportunity  is  given  to  him  for 
expressing  his  opinion  ;  and  no  call  is  made  upon  his 
intelligence  for  the  formation  of  any  opinion  whatsoever. 
In  short,  the  Boilermakers,  so  long  as  they  remained 
content  with  this  form  of  government,  secured  efficient 
administration  at  the  expense  of  losing  all  the  educative 
influences  and  political  safeguards  of  democracy. 

Among  the  well-organised  Coalminers  of  the  North  of 
England  the  theory  of  "direct  legislation  by  the  people" 
is  still  in  full  force.  Thus,  the  19,000  members  of  the 
Northumberland  Miners'  Mutual  Confident  Association  (estab- 
lished 1863)  decide  every  question  of  policy,  and  even  many 
merely  administrative  details,  by  the  votes  taken  in  the  several 
lodge  meetings  ; l  and  although  a  delegate  meeting  isTield 
every  quarter,  and  by  a  rule  of  1894  is  expressly  declared  to 
"  meet  for  the  purpose  of  deliberating  free  and  untrammelled 
upon  the  whole  of  the  programme,"  its  function  is  strictly 
limited  to  expressing  its  opinion,  the  entire  list  of  propositions 

1  See,  for  instance,  the  twenty-five  separate  propositions  voted  on  in  a  single 
batch,  gtli  June  1894. — Northumberland  Miners'  Minutes,  1894,  pp.  23-26. 


Primitive  Democracy  33 

being  then  "  returned  to  the  lodges  to  be  voted  on."  1  The 
executive  committee  is  elected  by  the  whole  body ;  and 
the  members,  who  retire  after  only  six  months'  service,  are 
ineligible  for  re-election.  Finally,  we  have  the  fact  that  the 
salaried  officials  are  themselves  elected  by  the  members  at  large. 
To  this  lack  of  organic  connection  between  the  different  parts 
of  the  constitution,  the  student  will  perhaps  attribute  a  certain 
instability  of  policy  manifested  in  successive  popular  votes. 
In  June  1894,  a  vote  of  all  the  members  was  taken  on  the 
question  of  joining  the  Miners'  Federation,  and  an  affirmative 
result  was  reached  by  6730  to  5807.  But  in  the  very  next 
month,  when  the  lodges  were  asked  whether  they  were  pre- 
pared to  give  effect  to  the  well-known  policy  of  the  Federa- 
tion and  claim  the  return  of  reductions  in  wages  amounting  to 
sixteen  per  cent,  which  they  had  accepted  since  1892,  they 
voted  in  the  negative  by  more  than  two  to  one  ;  and  backed 
this  up  by  an  equally  decisive  refusal  to  contribute  towards 
the  resistance  of  other  districts.  "  They  had  joined  a 
Federation  knowing  its  -principles  and  its  policy,  and  im- 
mediately after  joining  they  rejected  the  principles  they  had 
just  embraced,"  was  the  comment  of  one  of  the  members 

1  Rule  15.  We  see  here  a  curious  instance  of  the  express  separation  of  the 
deliberative  from  the  legislative  function,  arising  out  of  the  inconvenient  results 
of  the  use  of  the  Imperative  Mandate.  The  committee  charged  with  the  revision 
of  the  rules  in  1893-1894  reported  that  "the  present  mode  of  transacting  business 
at  delegate  meetings  has  long  been  felt  to  be  very  unsatisfactory.  Suggestions 
are  sent  in  for  programme  which  are  printed  and  remitted  to  the  lodges,  and 
delegates  are  then  sent  with  hard  and  fast  instructions  to  vote  for  or  against  as 
the  case  may  be.  It  not  unfrequently  happens  that  delegates  are  sent  to  support 
a  vote  against  suggestions  which  are  found  to  have  an  entirely  different  meaning, 
and  may  have  a  very  different  effect  from  those  expected  by  the  lodges  when 
voting  for  them.  To  avoid  the  mischief  that  has  frequently  resulted  from  our 
members  thus  committing  themselves  to  suggestions  upon  insufficient  information, 
we  suggest  that  after  the  programmes  have  been  sent  to  the  lodges,  lodges  send 
their  delegates  to  a  meeting  to  deliberate  on  the  business,  after  which  they  shall 
return  and  report  the  results  of  the  discussion  and  then  forward  their  votes  by 
proxy  to  the  office.  To  carry  out  this  principle,  which  we  consider  is  of  the 
greatest  possible  interest  and  importance  to  our  members,  no  more  meetings  will 
be  required  or  expense  incurred  than  under  the  present  system,  while  on  the  other 
hand  lodges  will  have  the  opportunity  of  casting  their  votes  on  the  various 
suggestions  with  full  information  before  them,  instead  of  in  the  absence  of  this 
information  in  most  cases,  as  at  present." — Report  of  3rd  February  1894,  in 
Northumberland  Miners'  Minutes,  1894,  pp.  87-88. 

VOL.  I  P 


34  Trade  Union  Structure 

of  their  own  executive  committee.1  This  inconsistent  action 
led  to  much  controversy,  and  the  refusal  of  the  Northumber- 
land men  to  obey  the  decision  of  the  special  conference,  the 
supreme  authority  of  the  Federation,  was  declared  to  be 
inconsistent  with  their  remaining  members  of  the  organisation. 
Nevertheless,  in  July  1894  they  again  voted,  by  8445  to 
5507,  in  favor  of  joining  the  Federation,  despite  the  power- 
ful adverse  influence  of  their  executive  committee.  The 
Federation  officials  not  unnaturally  asked  whether  the  re- 
newed application  for  membership  might  now  be  taken  to 
imply  a  willingness  to  conform  to  the  policy  of  the  organisa- 
tion which  it  was  wished  to  join.  On  this  a  further  vote  was 
taken  by  lodges,  when  the  proposition  to  join  was  negatived 
by  a  majority  of  over  five  to  one.2 

It  may  be  objected  that,  in  this  instance  of  joining  the 
Miners'  Federation,  the  question  at  issue  was  one  of  great 
difficulty  and  of  momentous  import  to  the  union,  and  that 
some  hesitation  on  the  part  of  the  members  was  only  to  be 
expected.  We  could,  however,  cite  many  similar  instances 
of  contradictory  votes  by  the  Northumberland  men,  on  both 
matters  of  policy  and  points  of  internal  administration.  We 
suggest  that  their  experience  is  only  another  proof  that, 
whatever  advantages  may  be  ascribed  to  government  by  the 
Referendum,  it  has  the  capital  drawback  of  not  providing  the 
executive  with  any  policy.  In  the  case  of  the  Northumber- 
land Miners'  Union,  the  result  has  been  a  serious  weakening 
of  its  influence,  and,  on  more  than  one  occasion,  the  gravest 

1  Report  of  Conference,  23rd   September    1893,  in  Northumberland  Miners' 
Minutes,  1893. 

2  It  should  be  explained  that  the  Referendum  among  the  Northumberland 
Miners  takes  two  distinct  forms,  the  "  ballot,"  and  the  so-called  "proxy  voting." 
Questions  relating  to  strikes,  and  any  others  expressly  ordered  by  the  delegate 
meeting,  are  decided  by  a  ballot  of  the  members  individually.      The  ordinary 
business   remitted  from  the  delegate  meeting  to  the  lodges  is  discussed  by  the 
general  meeting  of  each  lodge,  and  the  lodge  vote,  or  "proxy,"  is  cast  as  a  whole 
according  to  the  bare  majority  of  those  present.     The  lodge  vote  counts  from  one 
to  thirty,  in  strict  proportion  to  its  membership.      It  is  interesting  to  note  (though 
we  do  not  know  whether  any  inference  can  be  drawn  from  the  fact)  that  the  two 
votes  in  favor  of  the  Federation  were  taken  by  ballot  of  the  members,  whilst 
those  against  it  were  taken  by  the  "  proxy  "  of  the  lodges. 


Primitive  Democracy  35 

danger  of  disintegration.1  Fortunately,  the  union  has  enjoyed 
the  services  of  executive  officers  of  perfect  integrity,  and  of 
exceptional  ability  and  experience.  These  officers  have 
throughout  had  their  own  clearly  defined  and  consistent 
policy,  which  the  uninformed  and  contradictory  votes  of  the 
members  have  failed  to  control  or  modify. 

It  will  not  be  necessary  to  give  in  detail  the  constitution 
of  the  Durham  Miners'  Association  (established  1869),  since 
this  is,  in  essential  features,  similar  to  that  of  the  Northumber- 
land Miners.2  But  it  is  interesting  to  notice  that  the  Durham 
experience  of  the  result  of  government  by  the  Referendum 
has  been  identical  with  that  of  Northumberland,3  and  even 
more  detrimental  to  the  organisation.  The  Durham  Miners' 
Association,  notwithstanding  its  closely  concentrated  60,000 
members,  fails  to  exercise  any  important  influence  on  the 
Trade  Union  world,  and  even  excites  complaints  from  the 
employers  as  to  "  its  internal  weakness."  The  Durham  coal- 
owners  declare  that,  with  the  council  overruling  the  executive, 
and  the  ballot  vote  reversing  the  decision  of  the  council,  they 
never  know  when  they  have  arrived  at  a  settlement,  or  how 
long  that  settlement  will  be  enforced  on  a  recalcitrant  lodge. 

It  is  significant  that  the  newer  organisations  which  have 
sprung  up  in  these  same  counties  in  direct  imitation  of  the 
miners'  unions  give  much  less  power  to  the  members  at  large. 
Thus  the  Durham  Cokemen's  and  Laborers'  Association,  which, 
springing  out  of  the  Durham  Miners'  Association  in  1874, 
follows  in  its  rules  the  actual  phrases  of  the  parent  organisa- 
tion, vests  the  election  of  its  executive  committee  and  officers, 
not  in  the  members  at  large,  but  in  a  supreme  "  council." 

1  See,  for  instance,  the  report  of  the  special  conference  of  23rd  September 
1893,  expressly  summoned  to  resist  the  "disintegration  of  our  Association." — 
Northumberland  Miners'  Minutes,  1893. 

2  In   the  Durham  Miners'  Association  the  election  of  officers  is   nominally 
vested  in  the  council,  but  express  provision  is  made  in  the  rules  for  each  lodge  to 
"empower"  its  delegate  how  to  vote. 

3  This  may  be  seen,  for  instance,  from  the  incidental  references  to  the  Durham 
votes  given  in  the  Miners'  Federation  Minutes,  1893-1896;  or,  with  calamitous 
results,  in  the  history  of  the  great  Durham  strike  of  1892  ;  or  in  that  of  the  Silk- 
stone  strike  of  1891.     The  Durham  Miners'  Minutes  are  not  accessible  to  any 
non-member. 


^6  Trade  Union  Structure 

\j 

Much  the  same  may  be  said  of  the  Durham  County  Colliery 
Enginemen's  Mutual  Aid  Association,  established  1872;  the 
Durham  Colliery  Mechanics'  Association,  established  1879; 
and  (so  far  as  regards  the  election  of  officers)  the  Northumber- 
land Deputies'  Mutual  Aid  Association,  established  1887. 

If,  therefore,  democracy  means  that  everything  which 
"  concerns  all  should  be  decided  by  all,"  and  that  each  citizen 
should  enjoy  an  equal  and  identical  share  in  the  government, 
Trade  Union  history  indicates  clearly  the  inevitable  result. 
Government  by  such  contrivances  as  Rotation  of  Office,  the 
Mass  Meeting,  the  Referendum  and  Initiative,  or  the  Delegate 
restricted  by  his  Imperative  Mandate,  leads  straight  either  to 
inefficiency  and  disintegration,  or  to  the  uncontrolled  domin- 
ance of  a  personal  dictator  or  an  expert  bureaucracy.  Dimly 
and  almost  unconsciously  this  conclusion  has,  after  a  whole 
century  of  experiment,  forced  itself  upon  the  more  advanced 
trades.  The  old  theory  of  democracy  is  still  an  article 
of  faith,  and  constantly  comes  to  the  front  when  any  organi- 
sation has  to  be  formed  for  brand-new  purposes ;  *  but  Trade 
Union  constitutions  have  undergone  a  silent  revolution.  The 
old  ideal  of  the  Rotation  of  Office  among  all  the  members 
in  succession  has  been  practically  abandoned.  Resort  to  the 
aggregate  meeting  diminishes  steadily  in  frequency  and  im- 
portance. The  use  of  the  Initiative  and  the  Referendum  has 

1  We  may  refer,  by  way  of  illustration,  to  the  frequent  discussions  during 
1894-1895  among  the  members  of  the  political  association  styled  the  "  Independ- 
ent Labor  Party."  On  the  formation  of  the  Hackney  Branch,  for  instance,  the 
members  "decided  that  no  president  and  no  executive  committee  of  the  branch 
be  appointed,  its  management  devolving  on  the  members  attending  the  weekly 
conferences  "  (Labour  Leader,  26th  January  1895).  Nor  is  this  view  confined  to 
the  rank  and  file.  The  editor  of  the  Clarion  himself,  perhaps  the  most  influential 
man  in  the  party,  expressly  declared  in  his  leading  article  of  3rd  November  1894  : 
"Democracy  means  that  the  people  shall  rule  themselves;  that  the  people  shall 
manage  their  own  affairs  ;  and  that  their  officials  shall  be  public  servants,  or  dele- 
gates, deputed  to  put  the  will  of  the  people  into  execution.  ...  At  present  there 
is  too  much  sign  of  a  disposition  on  the  part  of  the  rank  and  file  to  overvalue  the 
talents  and  usefulness  of  their  officials.  ...  It  is  tolerably  certain  that  in  so 
far  as  the  ordinary  duties  of  officials  and  delegates,  such  as  committee  men  or 
members  of  Parliament,  are  concerned,  an  average  citizen,  if  he  is  thoroughly 
honest,  will  be  found  quite  clever  enough  to  do  all  that  is  needful.  .  .  .  Let  all 
officials  be  retired  after  one  year's  services,  and  fresh  ones  elected  in  their  place.' 


Primitive  Democracy  37 

been  tacitly  given  up  in  all  complicated  issues,  and  gradually 
limited  to  a  few  special  questions  on  particular  emergencies. 
The  delegate  finds  himself  every  year  dealing  with  more 
numerous  and  more  complex  questions,  and  tends  therefore 
inevitably  to  exercise  the  larger  freedom  of  a  representative. 
Finally,  we  have  the  appearance  in  the  Trade  Union  world  of 
the  typically  modern  form  of  democracy,  the  ejected-repfe- 
sentatiye  assembly,  appointing  and  controlling  an  executive 
committee^uTrder  whoseMdirection  the  permanent  official  staff 
performs  its  work, 


CHAPTER    II 

REPRESENTATIVE   INSTITUTIONS 

THE  two  organisations  in  the  Trade  Union  world  enjoying 
the  greatest  measure  of  representative  institutions  are  those 
which  are  the  most  distinctly  modern  in  their  growth  and  pre- 
eminence. In  numbers,  political  influence,  and  annual  income 
the  great  federal  associations  of  Coalminers  and  Cotton 
Operatives  overshadow  all  others,  and  now  comprise  one-fifth 
of  the  total  Trade  Union  membership.  We  have  elsewhere 
pointed  out  that  these  two  trades  are  both  distinguished  by 
their  establishment  of  an  expert  civil  service,  exceeding  in 
numbers  and  efficiency  that  possessed  by  any  other  trade.1 
They  resemble  each  other  also,  as  we  shall  now  see,  in  the 
success  with  which  they  have  solved  the  fundamental  problem 
of  democracy,  the  combination  of  administrative  efficiency 
and  popular  control.  In  each  case  the  solution  has  been 
found  in  the  frank  acceptance  of  representative  institutions. 

In  the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton- 
spinners,  which  may  be  taken  as  typical  of  cotton  organisa- 
tions, the  "legislative  power"  is  expressly  vested  "  in  a  meeting 
comprising  representatives  from  the  various  provinces  and  dis- 
tricts included  in  the  association." 2  This  "  Cotton-spinners' 
Parliament "  is  elected  annually  in  strict  proportion  to 

1  History  of  Trade   Unionism,  p.   298  ;  see  also  the  subsequent  chapter  on 
"The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining." 

2  Ruks  of  the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners  (Man- 
chester, 1894),  p.  4,  Rule  7. 


Representative  Institutions  39 

membership,  and  consists  of  about  a  hundred  representatives. 
It  meets  in  Manchester  regularly  every  quarter,  but  can  be 
called  together  by  the  executive  council  at  any  time.  Once 
elected,  this  assembly  is,  like  the  British  Parliament,  abso^ 
lutely  supreme.  Its  powers  and  functions  are  subject  to  no 
express  limitation,  and  from  its  decisions  there  is  no  appeal. 
The  rules  contain  no  provision  for  taking  a  vote  of  the 
members  ;  and  though  the  agenda  of  the  quarterly  meeting 
is  circulated  for  information  to  the  executives  of  the  district 
associations,  so  little  thought  is  there  of  any  necessity  for  the 
representatives  to  receive  a  mandate  from  their  constituents, 
that  express  arrangements  are  made  for  transacting  any  other 
business  not  included  in  the  agenda.1 

The  actual  "  government "  of  the  association  is  conducted 
by  an  executive  council  elected  by  the  general  representative 
meeting,  and  consisting  of  a  president,  treasurer,  and  secretary, 
with  thirteen  other  members,  of  whom  seven  at  least  must 
be  working  spinners,  whilst  the  other  six  are,  by  invariable 
custom,  the  permanent  officials  appointed  and  maintained 
by  the  principal  district  organisations.  Here  we  have  the 
"  cabinet "  of  this  interesting  constitution — the  body  which 
practically  directs  the  whole  work  of  the  association  and 
exercises  great  weight  in  the  counsels  of  the  legislative  body, 
preparing  its  agenda  and  guiding  all  its  proceedings.  For 
the  daily  work  of  administration  this  cabinet  is  authorised 
by  the  rules  to  appoint  a  committee,  the  "  sub-council,"  which 
consists  in  practice  of  the  six  "  gentlemen,"  as  the  district 
officials  are  commonly  called.  The  actual  executive  work  is 
performed  by  a  general  secretary,  who  himself  engages  such 
office  assistance  as  may  from  time  to  time  be  necessary.  In 
marked  contrast  with  all  the  Trade  Union  constitutions  which 
we  have  hitherto  described,  the  Cotton-spinners'  rules  do  not 

1  Rule  9,  p.  5.  The  general  representative  meeting  even  resembles  the  British 
Parliament  in  being  able  itself  to  change  the  fundamental  basis  of  the  constitution, 
including  the  period  of  its  own  tenure  of  office.  The  rules  upon  which  the 
Amalgamated  Association  depends  can  be  altered  by  the  general  representative 
meeting  in  a  session  called  by  special  notice,  without  any  confirmation  by  the 
constituents. — Rule  45,  pp.  27-28. 


40  Trade  Union  Structure 

give  the  election  of  this  chief  executive  officer  to  the  general 
body  of  members,  but  declare  expressly  that  "  the  sole  right 
of  electing  a  permanent  general  secretary  shall  be  vested  in 
the  provincial  and  district  representatives  when  in  meeting 
assembled,  by  whom  his  salary  shall  be  fixed  and  deter- 
mined." l  Moreover,  as  we  have  already  mentioned,  the 
candidates  for  this  office  pass  a  competitive  examination,  and 
when  once  elected  the  general  secretary  enjoys  a  permanence 
of  tenure  equal  to  that  of  the  English  civil  service,  the  rules 
providing  that  he  "  shall  be  appointed  and  continue  in  office 
so  long  as  he  gives  satisfaction."  2 

The  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton- 
spinners  is  therefore  free  from  all  the  early  expedients  for 
securing  popular  government.  The  general  or  aggregate 
meeting  finds  no  place  in  its  constitution,  and  the  rules  con- 
tain no  provision  for  the  Referendum  or  the  Initiative.  No 
countenance  is  given  to  the  idea  of  Rotation  of  Office.  No 
officers  are  elected  by  the  members  themselves.  Finally,  we 
have  the  complete  abandonment  of  the  delegate,  and  the  sub- 
stitution, both  in  fact  and  in  name,  of  the  representative.  On 
the  other  hand,  the  association  is  a  fully-equipped  democratic 
state  of  the  modern  type.  It  has  an  elected  parliament, 
exercising  supreme  and  uncontrolled  power.  It  has  a  cabinet 
appointed  by  and  responsible  only  to  that  parliament.  And 
its  chief  executive  officer,  appointed  once  for  all  on  grounds 
of  efficiency,  enjoys  the  civil-service  permanence  of  tenure.3 


1  Rule  12,  p.  6.  2 

3  The  other  branches  of  the  cotton  trade,  notably  the  federations  of  weavers 
and  cardroom  hands,  are  organised  on  the  same  principle  of  an  elected  repre- 
sentative assembly,  itself  appointing  the  officers  and  executive  committee,  though 
there  are  minor  .differences  among  them.  The  United  Textile  Factory  Workers' 
Association,  of  which  the  spinners  form  a  part,  is  framed  on  the  same  model, 
a  "legislative  council,"  really  an  executive  committee,  being  elected  by  the 
"conference,"  or  representative  assembly.  (This  organisation  temporarily 
suspended  its  functions  in  1896.)  Moreover,  the  rules  of  the  several  district 
associations  of  the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners  exhibit 
the  same  formative  influences.  In  the  smaller  societies,  confined  to  single 
villages,  we  find  the  simple  government  by  general  meeting,  electing  a  committee 
and  officers.  Permanence  of  tenure  is,  however,  the  rule,  it  being  often  expressly 
provided  that  the  secretary  and  the  treasurer  shall  each  "retain  office  as  long  as 
he  gives  satisfaction."  More  than  half  the  total  membership,  moreover,  is 


Representative  Institutions  41 

We  have  watched  the  working  of  this  remarkable  consti- 
tution during  the  last  seven  years,  and  we  can  testify  to  the 
success  with  which  both  efficiency  and  popular  control  are 
secured.  The  efficiency  we  attribute  to  the  existence  of 
the  adequate,  highly-trained,  and  relatively  well-paid  and 
permanent  civil  service.1  But  that  this  civil  service  is 
effectively  under  public  control  is  shown  by  the  accuracy 
with  which  the  cotton  officials  adapt  their  political  and 
industrial  policy  to  the  developing  views  of  the  members 
whom  they  serve.  This  sensitiveness  to  the  popular 
desires  is  secured  by  the  real  supremacy  of  the  elected 
representatives.  For  the  "  Cotton-spinners'  Parliament  "  is 
no  formal  gathering  of  casual  members  to  register  the  decrees 
of  a  dominant  bureaucracy.  It  is,  on  the  contrary,  a 
highly -organised  deliberative  assembly,  with  active  repre- 
sentatives from  the  different  localities,  each  alive  to  the  distinct, 
and  sometimes  divergent,  interests  of  his  own  constituents. 
Their  eager  participation  shows  itself  in  constant  "  party 
meetings  "  of  the  different  sections,  at  which  the  officers  and 
workmen  from  each  district  consult  together  as  to  the  line 
of  policy  to  be  pressed  upon  the  assembly.  Such  consulta- 
tion and  deliberate  joint  action  is,  in  the  case  of  the  Oldham 
representatives  at  any  rate,  carried  even  further.  The  consti- 
tution of  the  Oldham  Operative  Cotton-spinners'  Provincial 
Association  is,  so  far  as  we  know,  unique  in  all  the  annals  of 
democracy  in  making  express  provision  for  the  "  caucus." 2 

included  in  two  important  "  provinces,"  Oldham  and  Bolton,  which  possess 
elaborate  federal  constitutions  of  their  own.  These  follow,  in  general  outline, 
the  federal  constitution,  but  both  retain  some  features  of  the  older  form.  Thus 
in  Oldham,  where  the  officers  enjoy  permanence  of  tenure  and  are  responsible 
only  to  the  representative  assembly,  any  vacancy  is  filled  by  general  vote  of  the 
members.  And  though  the  representative  assembly  has  supreme  legislative  and 
executive  powers,  it  is  required  to  take  a  ballot  of  all  the  members  before  deciding 
on  a  strike.  On  the  other  hand,  Bolton,  which  leaves  everything  to  its  repre- 
sentative assembly,  shows  a  lingering  attachment  to  rotation  of  office  by  providing 
that  the  retiring  members  of  its  executive  council  shall  not  be  eligible  for  re-election 
during  twelve  months. 

1  The  nineteen  thousand  members  of  the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Opera- 
tive Cotton-spinners  command  the  services  of  ten  permanent  officials,  besides 
numerous  local  officers  still  working  at  their  trade. 

2  The  "  caucus,"  in  this  sense  of  the  term,   is  supposed  to  have  been  first 


4$  Trade  Union  Structure 

The  rules  of  1891  ordain  that  "whenever  the  business  to  be 
transacted  by  the  representatives  attending  the  quarterly 
or  special  meetings  of  the  Amalgamation  is  of  such  import- 
ance and  to  the  interest  of  this  association  as  to  require  unity 
of  action  in  regard  to  voting  by  the  representatives  from  this 
province,  the  secretary  shall  be  required  to  summon  a  special 
meeting  of  the  said  representatives  by  announcing  in  the 
monthly  circular  containing  the  minutes  the  date  and  time 
of  such  meeting,  which  must  be  held  in  the  council  room  at 
least  seven  days  previous  to  the  Amalgamation  meeting 
taking  place.  The  provincial  representatives  on  the  amalga- 
mated council  shall  be  required  to  attend  such  meeting,  to 
give  any  information  required,  and  all  resolutions  passed  by 
a  majority  of  those  present  shall  be  binding  upon  all  the 
representatives  from  the  Oldham  province  attending  the 
amalgamated  quarterly  or  special  meetings,  and  any  one 
acting  contrary  to  his  instructions  shall  cease  to  be  a  repre- 
sentative of  the  district  he  represents,  and  shall  not  be  allowed 
to  stand  as  a  candidate  for  any  office  connected  with  the 
association  for  the  space  of  twelve  months.  The  allowance 
for  attending  these  special  meetings  shall  be  in  accordance 
with  the  scale  allowed  to  the  provincial  executive  council."  1 
But  even  without  so  stringent  a  rule,  there  would  be  but 
little  danger  of  the  representatives  failing  to  express  the 
desires  of  the  rank  and  file.  Living  the  same  life  as  their 
constituents,  and  subject  to  annual  election,  they  can  scarcely 
fail  to  be  in  touch  with  the  general  body  of  the  members. 
The  common  practice  of  requiring  each  representative  to 
report  his  action  to  the  next  meeting  of  his  constituents,  by 
whom  it  is  discussed  in  his  presence,  and  the  wide  circulation 

introduced  about  the  beginning  of  this  century,  in  the  United  States  Congress,  by 
the  Democratic  Party.  See  the  Statesman's  Manual,  vol.  i.  pp.  294,  338  ; 
Woodrow  Wilson,  Congressional  Government ',  1 2th  edit.  (New  York,  1896),  pp. 
327-330;  Lalor's  Cyclopedia  of  Political  Science  (New  York,  1891),  vol.  i.  p. 
357.  The  "  caucus"  in  the  sense  of  "primary  assembly"  is  regulated  by  law 
in  many  American  States,  especially  in  Massachusetts.  See  Nominations  for 
Elective  Office  in  the  United  States,  by  F.  W.  Dallinger  (London,  1897). 

1  Rule  64,  pp.  41-42,  of  Rules  and  Regulations  for  the  Government  of  the 
Oldham  Operative  Cotton-spinners'  Provincial  Association  (Oldham,  1891). 


Representative  Institutions  43 

of  printed  reports  among  all  the  members  furnish  efficient 
substitutes  for  the  newspaper  press.  On  the  other  hand,  the 
facts  that  the  representative  assembly  is  a  permanent  insti- 
tution wielding  supreme  power,  and  that  in  practice  its 
membership  changes  little  from  year  to  year,  give  it  a  very 
real  authority  over  the  executive  council  which  it  elects  every 
six  months,  and  over  the  officers  whom  it  has  appointed. 
The  typical  member  of  the  "Cotton-spinners'  Parliament" 
is  not  only  experienced  in  voicing  the  desires  of  his 
constituents,  but  also  possesses  in  a  comparatively  large 
measure  that  knowledge  of  administrative  detail  and  of 
current  affairs  which  enables  him  to  understand  and  control 
the  proceedings  of  his  officers. 

The  Coalminers  are,  as  we  have  elsewhere  mentioned, 
not  so  unanimous  as  the  Cotton  Operatives  in  their 
adoption  of  representative  institutions.  The  two  great 
counties  of  Northumberland  and  Durham  have  unions  which 
preserve  constitutions  of  the  old-fashioned  type.  But  when 
we  pass  to  other  counties,  in  which  the  Miners  have  come 
more  thoroughly  under  the  influence  of  the  modern  spirit, 
we  find  representative  government  the  rule.  The  powerful 
associations  of  Yorkshire,  Lancashire,  and  the  Midlands  are 
all  governed  by  elected  representative  assemblies,  which 
appoint  the  executive  committees  and  the  permanent  officers. 
But  the  most  striking  example  of  the  adoption  of  repre- 
sentative institutions  among  the  Coalminers  is  presented  by 
the  Miners'  Federation  of  Great  Britain,  established  1887. 
This  great  federal  organisation,  which  now  comprises 
two -thirds  of  the  Coalminers  in  union,  adopted  from  the 
outset  a  completely  representative  constitution.  The  supreme 
authority  is  vested  in  a  "conference,"  summoned  as  often 
as  required,  consisting  of  representatives  elected  by  each 
county  or  district  association.  This  conference  exercises 
uncontrolled  power  to  determine  policy,  alter  rules,  and  levy 
unlimited  contributions.1  From  its  decision  there  is  no 

1  This  was  expressly  pointed  out,  doubtless  with  reference  to  some  of  the  old- 
fashioned  county  unions  which  still  clung  to  the  custom  of  the  Referendum  or  the 


44  Trade  Union  Structure 

appeal.  No  provision  is  made  for  taking  the  votes  of  the 
general  body  of  members,  and  the  conference  itself  appoints 
the  executive  committee  and  all  the  officers  of  the  Federa- 
tion. Between  the  sittings  of  the  conference  the  executive 
committee  is  expressly  given  power  to  take  action  to  promote 
the  interests  of  the  Federation,  and  no  rule  savoring  of 
Rotation  of  Office  deprives  this  executive  of  the  services  of 
its  experienced  members. 

The  "  Miners'  Parliament,"  as  this  conference  may  not 
improperly  be  termed,  is  in  many  respects  the  most  im- 
portant assembly  in  the  Trade  Union  world.  Its  regular 
annual  session,  held  in  some  midland  town,  lasts  often  for  a 
whole  week,  whilst  other  meetings  of  a  couple  of  days'  dura- 
tion are  held  as  business  requires.  The  fifty  to  seventy 
members,  who  represent  the  several  constituent  bodies,  consti- 
tute an  exceptionally  efficient  deliberative  assembly.  Among 
them  are  to  be  found  the  permanent  officers  of  the  county 
unions,  some  of  the  most  experienced  of  the  checkweigh-men 
and  the  influential  leaders  of  opinion  in  the  mining  villages. 
The  official  element,  as  might  be  expected,  plays  a  prominent 
part  in  suggesting,  drafting,  and  amending  the  actual  pro- 
posals, but  the  unofficial  members  frequently  intervene  with 
effect  in  the  business-like  debates.  The  public  and  the  press 
are  excluded,  but  the  conference  usually  directs  a  brief  and 
guarded  statement  of  the  conclusions  arrived  at  to  be  supplied 
to  the  newspapers,  and  a  full  report  of  the  proceedings — 
sometimes  extending  to  over  a  hundred  printed  pages — is 
subsequently  issued  to  the  lodges.  The  subjects  dealt  with 
include  the  whole  range  of  industrial  and  political  policy, 
from  the  technical  grievance  of  a  particular  district  up  to  the 
"  nationalisation  of  mines." l  The  actual  carrying  out  of  the 

Imperative  Mandate,  in  the  circular  summoning  the  important  conference  of 
July  1893  >  "Delegates  must  be  appointed  to  attend  Conference  with  full  power 
to  deal  with  the  wages  question." 

1  Thus  the  agenda  for  the  Annual  Conference  in  1894  comprised,  besides 
formal  business,  certain  revisions  of  rules  and  the  executive  committee's  report, 
the  Eight  Hours  Bill,  the  stacking  of  coal,  the  making  of  Saturday  a  regular 
whole  holiday,  the  establishment  of  a  public  department  to  prevent  unscrupulous 
competition  in  trade,  the  amendment  of  the  Mines  Regulation  and  Employers' 


Representative  Institutions  45 

policy  determined  on  by  the  conference  is  left  unreservedly 
to  the  executive  committee,  but  the  conference  expects  to  be 
called  together  whenever  any  new  departure  in  policy  is 
required.  In  times  of  stress  the  executive  committee  shows 
its  real  dependence  on  the  popular  assembly  by  calling  it 
together  every  few  weeks.1  And  the  success  with  which  the 
Miners'  Federation  wields  its  great  industrial  and  political 
power  over  an  area  extending  from  Fife  to  Somerset  and  a 

Liability  Acts,  international  relations  with  foreign  miners'  organisations  and  the 
nationalisation  of  mines.  It  may  here  be  observed  that  the  representatives  at 
the  Federal  Conference  have  votes  in  proportion  to  the  numbers  of  the  members 
in  their  respective  associations.  This  practice,  often  called  "proxy  voting,"  or, 
more  accurately,  "  the  accumulative  vote,"  has  long  been  characteristic  of  the 
Coalminers'  organisations,  though  unknown  to  any  other  section  of  the  Trade 
Union  World.  Thus  the  rules  of  the  Miners'  Federation  of  Great  Britain  are 
silent  as  to  the  number  of  representatives  to  be  sent  to  the  supreme  "  Conference," 
but  provide  "that  each  county,  federation  or  district  vote  upon  all  questions 
as  follows,  viz.  :  one  vote  for  every  1000  financial  members  or  fractional  part  of 
1000,  and  that  the  vote  in  every  case  shall  be  taken  by  numbers "  (Rule  lo, 
Rules  of  the  Miners'  Federation  of  Great  Britain,  1895).  A  similar 
principle  has  always  been  applied  at  the  International  Miners'  Conferences, 
and  the  practice  prevails  also  in  the  several  county  unions  or  federations.  The 
Lancashire  and  Cheshire  Federation  fixes  the  number  of  representatives  to  be 
sent  to  its  Conferences  at  one  per  500  members,  but  expressly  provides  that  the 
voting  is  to  be  "by  proxy"  in  the  same  proportion.  The  Midland  Federation 
adopts  the  same  rule.  The  Yorkshire,  Nottinghamshire,  Durham,  and  West 
Cumberland  associations  allow  each  branch  or  lodge  only  a  single  representative, 
whose  vote  counts  strictly  in  proportion  to  the  membership  he  represents.  This 
"accumulative  vote"  is  invariably  resorted  to  in  the  election  of  officers  and  in  all 
important  decisions  of  policy,  but  it  is  not  uncommon  for  minor  divisions  to  be 
taken,  unchallenged,  on  the  principle  of  "  one  man  one  vote."  It  is  not  easy  to 
account  for  the  exceptional  preference  of  the  Coalminers  for  this  method  of  voting, 
especially  as  their  assemblies  are,  as  we  have  pointed  out,  in  practice  more 
"  representative "  in  their  character,  and  less  trammelled  by  the  idea  of  the 
imperative  mandate,  than  those  of  any  other  trade  but  the  Cotton  Operatives. 
The  practice  facilitates,  it  is  true,  a  diminution  in  the  size  of  the  meetings,  but 
this  appears  to  be  its  only  advantage.  In  the  absence  of  any  system  of  "  pro- 
portional representation "  it  affords  no  real  guide  to  the  relative  distribution  of 
opinion  ;  the  representatives  of  Yorkshire,  for  instance,  in  casting  the  vote  of  the 
county,  can  at  best  express  the  views  only  of  the  majority  of  their  constituents, 
and  have  therefore  no  real  claim  to  outvote  a  smaller  district,  with  whose  views 
nearly  half  their  own  constituents  may  be  in  sympathy.  If,  on  the  other  hand, 
the  whole  membership  of  the  Miners'  Federation  were  divided  into  fairly  equal 
electoral  districts,  each  electing  a  single  member,  there  would  be  more  chance 
of  every  variety  of  opinion  being  represented,  whilst  an  exact  balance  between 
the  large  and  the  small  districts  would  nevertheless  be  preserved. 

1  During  the  great  strike  in   1893  the  Conference  met  eight  times  in  six 
months, 


46  Trade  Union  Structure 

membership  numbering  two  hundred  thousand,  furnishes 
eloquent  testimony  to  the  manner  in  which  it  has  known 
how  to  combine  efficient  administration  with  genuine  popular 
assent. 

The  great  federal  organisations  of  Cotton  Operatives  and 
Coalminers  stand  out  from  among  the  other  Trade  Unions 
in  respect  of  the  completeness  and  success  with  which  they 
have  adopted  representative  institutions.  But  it  is  easy  to 
trace  a  like  tendency  throughout  the  whole  Trade  Union 
world.  We  have  already  commented  on  the  innovation, 
now  almost  universal,  of  entrusting  the  task  of  revising  rules 
to  a  specially  elected  committee.  It  was  at  first  taken  for 
granted  that  the  work  of  such  a  revising  committee  was 
limited  to  putting  into  proper  form  the  amendments  pro- 
posed by  the  branches  themselves,  and  sometimes  to  choosing 
between  them.  Though  it  is  still  usual  for  the  revised  rules 
to  be  formally  ratified  by  a  vote  of  the  members,  the  revising 
committees  have  been  given  an  ever  wider  discretion,  until 
in  most  unions  they  are  nowadays  in  practice  free  to  make 
changes  according  to  their  own  judgment.1  But  it  is  in 
the  constitution  of  the  central  executive  that  the  trend 
towards  representative  institutions  is  most  remarkable,  the 
old  expedient  of  the  "  governing  branch  "  being  superseded 
by  an  executive  committee  representative  of  the  whole  body 
of  the  members.2 

1  There  is  a  similar  tendency  to  disapprove  of  the  Imperative  Mandate  in  the 
principal   Friendly   Societies.      The   Friendly  Societies'   Monthly  Magazine  for 
April  1890  observes  that  "  Lodges  are  advised  ...   to  instruct  their  delegates 
as  to  how  they  are  to  vote.     With  this  we  entirely  disagree.     A  proposition  till 
it  is  properly  thrashed  out  and  explained,  remains  in  the  husk,  and  its  full  import 
is   lost.     Delegates  fettered   with    instructions   simply  become    the    mechanical 
mouthpiece  of  the  necessarily  unenlightened  lodges  which  send  them,  and  there- 
fore the  legislation  of  the  Order  might  just  as  well  be  conducted  by  post." 

2  Thus  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Railway  Servants   (established    1872) 
administers  the  affairs  of  its  forty-four  thousand  members  by  an  executive  committee 
of  thirteen  (with  the  three  officers),  elected  annually  by  ballot  in  thirteen  equal 
electoral  districts.      This  committee  meets  in   London  at  least    quarterly,  and 
can  be  summoned  oftener  if  required.      Above  this  is  the  supreme  authority  of 
the  annual  assembly  of  sixty  delegates,  elected  by  sixty  equal  electoral  districts, 
and  sitting  for  four  days  to  hear  appeals,  alter  rules,  and  determine  the  policy  of 
the  union.       A  similar  constitution  is   enjoyed  by  the  Associated    Society  of 


Representative  Institutions  47 

This  revolution  has  taken  place  in  the  National  Union 
of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  (37,000  members)  and  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  (87,313  members),  the 
two  societies  which,  outside  the  worlds  of  cotton  and  coal, 
exceed  nearly  all  others  in  membership.  Down  to  1890  the 
National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  was  governed 
by  a  local  executive  council  belonging  to  a  single  town, 
controlled  only  by  occasional  votes  of  a  delegate  assembly, 
meeting,  at  first,  every  four  years,  and  afterwards  every  two 
years.  Seven  years  ago  the  constitution  was  entirely  trans- 
formed. The  society  was  divided  into  five  equal  electoral 
districts,  each  of  which  elected  one  member  to  serve  for  two 
years  on  an  executive  council  consisting  of  only  these  five 
representatives,  in  addition  to  the  three  other  officers  elected 
by  the  whole  body  of  members.  To  the  representative  execu- 
tive thus  formed  was  committed  not  only  all  the  ordinary 
business  of  the  society,  but  also  the  final  decision  in  cases  of 
appeals  by  individual  members  against  the  decision  of  a 
branch.  The  delegate  meeting,  or  "  National  Conference," 
meets  to  determine  policy  and  revise  rules,  and  its  decisions 
no  longer  require  ratification  by  the  members'  vote.  Although 
the  Referendum  and  the  Mass  Meeting  of  the  district  are 
still  formally  included  in  the  constitution,  the  complication 
and  difficulty  of  the  issues  which  have  cropped  up  during  the 
last  few  years  have  led  the  executive  council  to  call  together 
the  national  conference  at  frequent  intervals,  in  preference 
to  submitting  questions  to  the  popular  vote. 

Locomotive  Enginemen  and  Firemen  (established  1880).  It  is  this  model  that 
has  been  followed,  with  unimportant  variations  in  detail,  by  the  more  durable  of 
the  labor  unions  which  sprang  into  existence  in  the  great  upheaval  of  1889, 
among  which  the  Gasworkers  and  the  Dockers  are  the  best  known.  The  practice 
of  electing  the  executive  committee  by  districts  is,  as  far  as  we  know,  almost 
unknown  in  the  political  world.  The  executive  council  of  the  State  of  Penn- 
sylvania in  the  eighteenth  century  used  to  be  elected  by  single -member 
districts  (Federalist,  No.  LVII.),  and  a  similar  arrangement  appears  occa- 
sionally to  have  found  a  place  in  the  ever-changing  constitutions  of  one  or  two 
Swiss  Cantons.  (See  State  and  Federal  Government  in  Switzerland,  by 
J.  M.  Vincent,  Baltimore,  1891.)  We  know  of  no  case  where  it  prevails 
at  present  (Lowell's  Governments  and  Parties  in  Continental  Europe,  London, 
1896). 


48  Trade  Union  Structure 

In  the  case  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers 
the  constitutional  revolution  has  been  far  more  sweeping. 
In  the  various  editions  of  the  Engineers'  rules  from  1851  to 
1891  we  find  the  usual  reliance  on  the  Mass  Meeting,  the 
Referendum  and  the  direct  election  of  all  officers  by  the 
members  at  large.  We  also  see  the  executive  control  vested 
in  a  committee  elected  by  a  single  district, — the  chairman, 
moreover,  being  forbidden  to  serve  for  more  than  two  years 
in  succession.  In  the  case  of  the  United  Society  of  Boiler- 
makers we  have  already  described  how  a  constitution  of 
essentially  similar  type  has  resulted  in  remarkable  success 
and  efficiency,  but  at  the  sacrifice  of  all  real  control  by  the 
members.  In  the  history  of  the  Boilermakers  from  1872 
onwards  we  watch  the  virtual  abandonment  in  practice,  for 
the  sake  of  a  strong  and  united  central  administration,  of 
everything  that  tended  to  weaken  the  executive  power. 
The  Engineers,  on  the  contrary,  clung  tenaciously  to  every 
institution  or  formality  which  protected  the  individual 
member  against  the  central  executive.1  Meanwhile,  although 
the  very  object  of  the  amalgamation  in  1851  was  to  secure 
uniformity  of  trade  policy,  the  failure  to  provide  any  salaried 
official  staff  left  the  central  executive  with  little  practical 
control  over  the  negotiations  conducted  or  the  decisions 
arrived  at  by  the  local  branch  or  district  committee.  The 
result  was  not  only  failure  to  cope  with  the  vital  problems 

1  In  financial  matters,  for  instance,  though  every  penny  of  the  funds  belonged 
to  the  whole  society,  each  branch  retained  its  own  receipts,  subject  only  to  the 
cumbrous  annual  "equalisation."  The  branch  accordingly  had  it  in  its  power  to 
make  any  disbursement  it  chose,  subject  only  to  subsequent  disallowance  by  the 
central  executive.  Nor  was  the  decision  of  the  central  executive  in  any  way 
final.  The  branch  aggrieved  by  any  disallowance  could,  and  habitually  did, 
appeal — not  to  the  members  at  large,  who  would  usually  have  supported  the 
executive— but  to  another  body,  the  general  council,  which  met  every  three  years 
for  the  express  purpose  of  deciding  such  appeals.  There  was  even  a  further 
appeal  from  the  general  council  to  the  periodical  delegate  meeting.  In  the 
meantime  the  payment  objected  to  was  not  required  to  be  refunded,  and  it  will 
therefore  easily  be  understood  that  the  vast  majority  of  executive  decisions  were 
instantly  appealed  against.  And  when  we  add  that  each  of  these  several  courts 
of  appeal  frequently  reversed  a  large  proportion  of  the  decisions  of  its  immediate 
inferior,  the  effect  of  these  frequent  appeals  in  destroying  all  authority  can  easily 
be  imagined. 


Representative  Institutions  49 

of  trade  policy  involved  in  the  changing  conditions  of  the 
industry,  but  also  an  increasing  paralysis  of  administration, 
against  which  officers  and  committee-men  struggled  in  vain. 
When  in  1892  the  delegates  met  at  Leeds  to  find  a  remedy 
for  these  evils,  they  brought  from  the  branches  two  leading  N 
suggestions.  One  party  urged  the  appointment,  in  aid  of 
the  central  executive,  of  a  salaried  staff  of  district  delegates, 
elected,  in  direct  imitation  of  those  of  the  Boilermakers,  by 
the  whole  society.  Another  section  favored  the  transforma" 
tion  of  the  executive  committee  into  a  representative  body, 
and  proposed  the  division  of  the  country  into  eight  equal 
electoral  districts,  each  of  which  should  elect  a  representative 
to  a  salaried  executive  council  sitting  continually  in  London, 
and  thus  giving  its  whole  time  to  the  society's  work. 
Probably  these  remedies,  aimed  at  different  sides  of  the 
trouble,  were  intended  as  alternatives.  It  is  significant  of 
the  deep  impression  made  upon  the  delegate  meeting  that  it 
eventually  adopted  both,  thus  at  one  blow  increasing  the 
number  of  salaried  officers  from  three  to  seventeen.1 

Time  has  yet  to  show  how  far  this  revolution  in  the 
constitution  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  will 
conduce  either  to  efficient  administration  or  to  genuine 
popular  control.  It  is  easy  to  see  that  government  by 
an  executive  committee  of  this  character  differs  essentially 
from  government  by  a  representative  assembly  appointing 
its  own  cabinet,  and  that  it  possesses  certain  obvious  dis- 
advantages. The  eight  members,  who  are  thus  transferred 
by  the  vote  of  their  fellows  from  the  engineer's  workshop  to. 
the  Stamford  Street  office,  become  by  this  fundamental 
change  of  life  completely  severed  from  their  constituents. 
Spending  all  their  days  in  office  routine,  they  necessarily 
lose  the  vivid  appreciation  of  the  feelings  of  the  man 

1  It  is  interesting  to  observe  that  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  by 
adopting  in  1895  a  Representative  Executive,  has  made  its  formal  constitution 
almost  identical  with  that  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers.  The  vital 
difference  between  these  two  societies  now  lies  in  the  working  relation  between 
the  central  executive  and  the  local  branches  and  district  committees ;  see  the 
subsequent  chapter  on  "The  Unit  of  Government." 

VOL.  I  E 


50  Trade  Union  Structure 

who  works  at  the  lathe  or  the  forge.  Living  constantly  in 
London,  they  are  subject  to  new  local  influences,  and  tend 
unconsciously  to  get  out  of  touch  with  the  special  grievances 
or  new  drifts  of  popular  opinion  on  the  Tyne  or  the  Clyde, 
at  Belfast  or  in  Lancashire.  It  is  true  that  the  representa- 
tives hold  office  for  only  three  years,  at  the  expiration  of 
which  they  must  present  themselves  for  re-election ;  but 
there  would  be  the  greatest  possible  reluctance  amongst  the 
members  to  relegate  to  manual  labor  a  man  who  had  once 
served  them  as  a  salaried  official.  Unless,  therefore,  a  re- 
vulsion of  feeling  takes  place  among  the  Engineers  against 
the  institution  itself,  the  present  members  of  the  representa- 
tive executive  committee  may  rely  with  some  confidence  on 
becoming  practically  permanent  officials. 

These  objections  do  not  apply  with  equal  force  to  other 
examples  of  a  representative  executive.  The  tradition  of 
the  Stamford  Street  office — that  the  whole  mass  of  friendly- 
society  business  should  be  dealt  with  in  all  its  details  by  the 
members  of  the  executive  committee  themselves — involves 
their  daily  attendance  and  their  complete  absorption  in 
office  work.  In  other  Trade  Unions  which  have  adopted 
the  same  constitutional  form,  the  members  of  the  represent- 
ative executive  reside  in  their  constituencies  and,  in  some 
cases,  even  continue  to  work  at  their  trade.  They  are  called 
together,  like  the  members  of  a  representative  assembly,  at 
quarterly  or  other  intervals  to  decide  only  the  more  im- 
portant questions,  the  detailed  executive  routine  being 
delegated  to  a  local  sub -committee  or  to  the  official  staff. 
Thus  the  executive  committee  of  the  National  Union  of 
Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  usually  meets  only  for  one  day 
a  month  ;  the  executive  committee  of  the  Associated  Loco- 
motive Engineers  and  Firemen  is  called  together  only  when 
required,  usually  not  more  than  once  or  twice  a  month ;  the 
executive  council  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Railway 
Servants  comes  to  London  once  a  quarter,  and  the  same 
practice  is  followed  by  the  executive  committee  of  the 
National  Union  of  Gasworkers  and  General  Laborers.  It  is 


Representative  Institutions  5 1 

evident  that  in  all  these  cases  the  representative  executive, 
whether  formed  of  the  salaried  officials  of  the  districts  or  of 
men  working  at  their  trade,  has  more  chance  of  remaining  in 
touch  with  its  constituents  than  in  the  case  of  the  Amalga- 
mated Society  of  Engineers. 

But  there  is,  in  our  opinion,  a  fundamental  drawback  to 
government  by  a  representative  executive,  even  under  the 
most  favorable  conditions.  One  of  the  chief  duties  of  a 
representative  governing  body  is  to  critin'sp.  ^control,  and 
direct  the  permanent  official  staff,  by  whom  the  policy  of  the 
"organisation  muyractualljTbe  carried  out.  Its  main  function, 
in  fact,  is  to  exercise  real  and  continuous  authority  over  the 
civil  service.  Now  all  experience  shows  it  to  be  an  essential 
condition  that  the  permanent  officials  should  be  dependent 
on  and  genuinely  subordinate  to  the  representative  body. 
This  condition  is  fulfilled  in  the  constitutions  such  as  those 
of  the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners 
and  the  Miners'  Federation,  where  the  representative  assembly 
itself  appoints  the  officers,  determines  their  duties,  and  fixes 
their  salaries.  But  it  is  entirely  absent  in  all  Trade  Union 
constitutions  based  on  a  representative  executive.  Under  this 
arrangement  the  executive  committee  neither  appoints  the 
officers  nor  fixes  their  salaries.  Though  the  representative 
executive,  unlike  the  old  governing  branch,  can  in  its  corporate 
capacity  claim  to  speak  in  the  name  of  all  the  members,  so 
can  the  general  secretary  himself,  and  often  each  assistant 
secretary.  All  alike  hold  their  positions  from  the  same 
supreme  power — the  votes  of  the  members ;  and  have  their 
respective  duties  and  emoluments  defined  by  the  same 
written  constitution — the  society's  rules. 

This  absence  of  any  co-ordination  of  the  several  parts 
of  the  constitution  works  out,  in  practice,  in  one  of  two 
ways.  There  may  arise  jealousies  between  the  several  officers, 
or  between  them  and  some  of  the  members  of  the  executive 
committee.  We  have  known  instances  in  which  an  incom- 
petent and  arbitrary  general  secretary  has  been  pulled  up 
by  one  or  other  of  his  colleagues  who  wanted  to  succeed  to 


52  Trade  Union  Structure 

his  place.  The  suspicion  engendered  by  the  relation  of 
competitors  for  popular  suffrage  checks,  it  may  be,  some 
positive  malpractices,  but  results  also  in  the  obstruction  of 
useful  measures  of  policy,  or  even  in  their  failure  through  dis- 
loyalty. More  usually  the  executive  committee,  feeling  itself 
powerless  to  control  the  officials,  tends  to  make  a  tacit 
and  half-unconscious  compact  with  them,  based  on  mutual 
support  against  the  criticism  of  their  common  constituents. 
If  the  members  of  the  committee  are  themselves  salaried 
officials,  they  not  only  have  a  fellow-feeling  for  the  weak- 
nesses of  their  brother  officials,  but  they  also  realise  vividly 
the  personal  risk  of  appealing  against  them  to  the  popular 
vote.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  members  continue  to  work 
at  their  trade,  they  feel  themselves  at  a  hopeless  disadvantage 
in  any  such  appeal.  They  have  neither  the  business  ex- 
perience nor  the  acquaintance  with  details  necessary  for  a 
successful  indictment  of  an  officer  who  is  known  from  one 
end  of  the  society  to  the  other,  and  who  enjoys  the  advantage 
of  controlling  its  machinery.  Thus  we  have  in  many  unions 
governed  by  a  Representative  Executive  the  formation  of 
a  ruling  clique,  half  officials,  half  representatives.  This 
has  all  the  disadvantages  of  such  a  bureaucracy  as  we  have 
described  in  the  case  of  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers, 
without  the  efficiency  made  possible  by  its  hierarchical 
organisation  and  the  predominant  authority  of  the  head  of 
the  staff.  To  sum  up,  if  there  are  among  the  salaried  repre- 
sentatives or  officials  restless  spirits,  "  conscientious  critics,"  or 
disloyal  comrades,  the  general  body  of  members  may  rest 
assured  that  they  will  be  kept  informed  of  what  is  going  on, 
but  at  the  cost  of  seeing  their  machinery  of  government 
constantly  clogged  by  angry  recriminations  and  appeals.  If, 
on  the  other  hand,  the  men  who  meet  at  headquarters  in 
one  or  another  capacity  are  "good  fellows,"  the  machine 
will  work  smoothly  with  such  efficiency  as  their  industry  and 
capacity  happens  to  be  equal  to,  but  all  popular  control 
over  this  governing  clique  will  disappear. 

We  see,  then,  that  though  government  by  a  representa- 


Representative  Institutions  53 

tive  executive  is  a  real  advance  on  the  old  expedients,  it  is 
likely  to  prove  inferior  to  government  by  a  representative 
assembly,  appointing  its  own  cabinet  and  officers.  But  a 
great  national  Trade  Union  extending  from  one  end  of  the 
kingdom  to  the  other  cannot  easily  adopt  the  superior  form, 
even  if  the  members  desire  it.  The  Cotton  Operatives  enjoy 
the  special  advantage  of  having  practically  all  their  member- 
ship within  a  radius  of  thirty  miles  from  Manchester.  The 
frequent  gatherings  of  a  hundred  delegates  held  usually  on 
a  Saturday  afternoon  entail,  therefore,  no  loss  of  working 
time  and  little  expense  to  the  organisation.  The  same  con- 
sideration applies  to  the  great  bulk  of  the  membership  of 
the  Miners'  Federation,  three-fourths  of  which  is  concentrated 
in  Lancashire,  West  Yorkshire,  and  the  industrial  Midlands. 
Even  the  outlying  coalfields  elsewhere  enjoy  the  advantage 
of  close  local  concentration,  so  that  a  single  delegate  may 
effectively  represent  the  hundreds  of  lodges  in  his  own 
county.  And  it  is  no  small  consideration  that  the  total 
membership  of  the  Miners'  Federation  is  so  large  that  the 
cost  of  frequent  meetings  of  fifty  to  seventy  delegates  bears 
only  a  trifling  proportion  to  the  resources  of  the  union. 
Very  different  is  the  position  of  the  great  unions  in  the 
engineering  and  building  trades.  The  46,000  members  of  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Carpenters  in  the  United  Kingdom, 
for  instance,  are  divided  into  623  branches,  scattered  over 
400  separate  towns  or  villages.  Each  town  has  its  own 
Working  Rules,  its  own  Standard  Rate  and  Normal  Day,  and 
lacks  intimate  connection  with  the  towns  right  and  left  of  it. 
The  representative  chosen  by  the  Newcastle  branch  might 
easily  be  too  much  absorbed  by  the  burning  local  question  of 
demarcation  against  the  Shipwrights  to  pay  much  attention 
to  the  simple  grievances  of  the  Hexham  branch  as  to  the 
Saturday  half-holiday,  or  to  the  multiplication  of  apprentices 
in  the  joinery  shops  at  Darlington.  Similar  considerations 
apply  to  the  497  branches  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Engineers,  whose  80,000  members  in  the  United  Kingdom 
are  working  in  300  different  towns.  In  view  of  the  increasing 


54  Trade  Union  Structicre 

uniformity  of  working  conditions  throughout  the  country,  the 
concentration  of  industry  in  large  towns,  the  growing  facili- 
ties of  travel  and  the  steady  multiplication  of  salaried  local 
officials," we  do  not  ourselves  regard  the  geographical  difficulty 
as  insuperable.  But  it  is  easy  to  understand  why,  with  so 
large  a  number  of  isolated  branches,  it  has  not  yet  seemed 
practicable  to  constitutional  reformers  in  the  building  or 
the  engineering  trades,  to  have  frequent  meetings  of  repre- 
sentative assemblies. 

The  tardiness  and  incompleteness  with  which  Trade 
Unions  have  adopted  representative  institutions  is  mainly 
due  to  a  more  general  cause.  The  workman  has  been  slow 
to  recognise  the  special  function  of  the  representative  in  a 
democracy.  In  the  early  constitutional  ideals  of  Trade 
Unionism  the  representative  finds,  as  we  have  seen,  absolutely 
no  place.  The  committee-man  elected  by  rotation  of  office 
or  the  delegate  deputed  to  take  part  in  a  revision  of  rules 
was  habitually  regarded  only  as  a  vehicle  by  which  "the 
voices  "  could  be  mechanically  conveyed.  His  task  required, 
therefore,  no  special  qualification  beyond  intelligence  to 
comprehend  his  instructions  and  a  spirit  of  obedience  in 
carrying  them  out.  Very  different  is  the  duty  cast  upon 
the  representative  in  such  modern  Trade  Union  constitutions 
as  those  of  the  Cotton  Operatives  and  Coalminers.  His 
main  function  is  still  to  express  the  mind  of  the  average 
man.  But  unlike  the  delegate,  he  is  not  a  mechanical 
vehicle  of  votes  on  particular  subjects.  The  ordinary  Trade 
Unionist  has  but  little  facility  in  expressing  his  desires ; 
unversed  in  the  technicalities  of  administration,  he  is  unable 
to  judge  by  what  particular  expedient  his  grievances  can 
best  be  remedied.  In  default  of  an  expert  representative  he 
has  to  depend  on  the  professional  administrator.  But  for 
this  particular  task  the  professional  administrator  is  no  more 
competent  than  the  ordinary  man,  though  for  a  different 
reason.  The  very  apartness  of  his  life  from  that  of  the 
average  workman  deprives  him  of  close  acquaintance  with 
the  actual  grievances  of  the  mass  of  the  people.  Immersed 


Representative  Institutions  55 

in  office  routine,  he  is  apt  to  fail  to  understand  from  their 
inconsistent  complaints  and  impracticable  suggestions  what 
it  is  they  really  desire.  To  act  as  an  interpreter  between 
the  people  and  their  servants  is,  therefore,  the  first  function 
of  the  representative. 

But  this  is  only  half  of  his  duty.  To  him  is  entrusted 
also  the  difficult  and  delicate  task  of  controlling  the  pro- 
fessional experts.  Here,  as  we  have  seen,  the  ordinary  man 
completely  breaks  down.  The  task,  to  begin  with,  requires 
a  certain  familiarity  with  the  machinery  of  government,  and 
a  sacrifice  of  time  and  a  concentration  of  thought  out  of  the 
reach  of  the  average  man  absorbed  in  gaining  his  daily 
bread.  So  much  is  this  the  case  that  when  the  administra- 
tion is  complicated,  a  further  specialisation  is  found  necessary, 
and  the  representative  assembly  itself  chooses  a  cabinet,  or 
executive  committee  of  men  specially  qualified  for  this  duty. 
A  large  measure  of  intuitive  capacity  to  make  a  wise  choice 
of  men  is,  therefore,  necessary  even  in  the  ordinary  repre- 
sentative. Finally,  there  comes  the  important  duty  of 
deciding  upon  questions  of  policy  or  tactics.  The  ordinary 
citizen  thinks  of  nothing  but  clear  issues  on  broad  lines. 
The  representative,  on  the  other  hand,  finds  himself  con- 
stantly called  upon  to  choose  between  the  nicely  balanced 
expediencies  of  compromise  necessitated  by  the  complicated 
facts  of  practical  life.  On  his  shrewd  judgment  of  actual 
circumstances  will  depend  his  success  in  obtaining,  not  all 
that  his  constituents  desire — for  that  he  will  quickly  recognise 
as  Utopian, — but  the  largest  instalment  of  those  desires 
that  may  be  then  and  there  possible. 

To  construct  a  perfect  representative  assembly  can, 
therefore,  never  be  an  easy  task  ;  and  in  a  community  ex- 
clusively composed  of  manual  workers  dependent  on  weekly 
wages,  the  task  is  one  of  exceptional  difficulty.  A 
community  of  bankers  and  business  entrepreneurs  finds  it 
easy  to  secure  a  representative  committee  to  direct  and 
control  the  paid  officials  whom  it  engages  to  protect  its 
interests.  Constituents,  representatives  and  officials  are 


56  Trade  Union  Structure 

living  much  the  same  life,  are  surrounded  by  the  same 
intellectual  atmosphere,  have  received  approximately  the 
same  kind  of  education  and  mental  training,  and  are  con- 
stantly engaged  in  one  variety  or  another  of  what  is 
essentially  the  same  work  of  direction  and  control.  More- 
over, there  is  no  lack  of  persons  able  to  give  the  necessary 
time  and  thought  to  expressing  the  desires  of  their  class  and 
to  seeing  that  they  are  satisfied.  It  is,  therefore,  not 
surprising  that  representative  institutions  should  be  seen 
at  their  best  in  middle- class  communities.1  In  all  these 
respects  the  manual  workers  stand  at  a  grave  disadvantage. 
Whatever  may  be  the  natural  endowment  of  the  workman 
selected  by  his  comrades  to  serve  as  a  representative,  he 
starts  unequipped  with  that  special  training  and  that  general 
familiarity  with  administration  which  will  alone  enable  him 
to  be  a  competent  critic  and  director  of  the  expert  pro- 
fessional. Before  he  can  place  himself  on  a  level  with  the 
trained  official  whom  he  has  to  control  he  must  devote  his 
whole  time  and  thought  to  his  new  duties,  and  must  there- 
fore give  up  his  old  trade.  This  unfortunately  tends  to 
alter  his  manner  of  life,  his  habit  of  mind,  and  usually  also 
his  intellectual  atmosphere  to  such  an  extent  that  he 
gradually  loses  that  vivid  appreciation  of  the  feelings  of  the 
man  at  the  bench  or  the  forge,  which  it  is  his  function  to 
express.  There  is  a  certain  cruel  irony  in  the  problem 
which  accounts,  we  think,  for  some  of  the  unconscious 
exasperation  of  the  wage-earners  all  over  the  world  against 
representative  institutions.  Directly  the  working-man 
representative  becomes  properly  equipped  for  one -half  of 
his  duties,  he  ceases  to  be  specially  qualified  for  the  other. 
If  he  remains  essentially  a  manual  worker,  he  fails  to  cope 
with  the  brain-working  officials  ;  if  he  takes  on  the  character 
of  the  brain-worker,  he  is  apt  to  get  out  of  touch  with 
the  constituents  whose  desires  he  has  to  interpret.  It  will, 
therefore,  be  interesting  to  see  how  the  shrewd  workmen  of 

1  In  this  connection  see  the  interesting  suggestions  of  Achille  Loria,  Les  Bases 
Economiques  de  la  Constitution  Sociale  (Paris,  1893),  PP-  150-154. 


Representative  Institutions  57 

Lancashire,  Yorkshire,  and  the  Midlands  have  surmounted 
this  constitutional  difficulty. 

In  the  parliaments  of  the  Cotton-spinners  and  Coalminers 
we  find  habitually  two  classes  of  members,  salaried  officials 
of  the  several  districts,  and  representative  wage-earners  still 
working  at  the  mule  or  in  the  mine.  It  would  almost  seem 
as  if  these  modern  organisations  had  consciously  recognised 
the  impossibility  of  combining  in  any  individual  representa- 
tive both  of  the  requirements  that  we  have  specified.  As  it 
is,  the  presence  in  their  assemblies  of  a  large  proportion  of 
men  who  are  still  following  their  trade  imports  into  their 
deliberations  the  full  flavor  of  working-class  sentiment.  And 
the  association,  with  these  picked  men  from  each  industrial 
village,  of  the  salaried  officers  from  each  county,  secures  that 
combination  of  knowledge,  ability,  and  practical  experience 
in  administration,  which  is,  as  we  have  suggested,  absolutely 
indispensable  for  the  exercise  of  control  over  the  professional 
experts.  If  the  constituencies  elected  none  but  their  fellow- 
workers,  it  is  more  than  doubtful  whether  the  representative 
assembly  so  created  would  be  competent  for  its  task.  If, 
on  the  other  hand,  the  assembly  consisted  merely  of  a 
conference  of  salaried  officials,  appointing  one  or  more  of 
themselves  to  carry  out  the  national  work  of  the  federation, 
it  would  inevitably  fail  to  retain  the  confidence,  even  if  it 
continued  to  express  the  desires  of  the  members  at  large. 
The  conjunction  of  the  two  elements  in  the  same  repre- 
sentative assembly  has  in  practice  resulted  in  a  very  efficient 
working  body. 

It  is  important  to  notice  that  in  each  of  the  trades  the 
success  of  the  experiment  has  depended  on  the  fact  that  the 
organisation  is  formed  on  a  federal  basis.  The  constituent 
bodies  of  the  Miners'  Federation  and  the  Amalgamated 
Association  of  Operative  Cotton  -  spinners  have  their 
separate  constitutions,  their  distinct  funds,  and  their  own 
official  staffs.  The  salaried  officers  whom  they  elect  to  sit  as 
representatives  in  the  federal  parliament  have,  therefore,  quite 
other  interests,  obligations,  and  responsibilities  than  those  of 


58  Trade  Union  Structure 

the  official  staff  of  the  Federation  itself.  The  secretary  of 
the  Nottinghamshire  Miners'  Association,  for  instance,  finds 
himself  able,  when  sitting  as  a  member  of  the  Conference  of 
the  Miners'  Federation,  freely  to  criticise  the  action  of  the 
federal  executive  council  or  of  the  federal  official  staff,  with- 
out in  any  way  endangering  his  own  position  as  a  salaried 
officer.  Similarly,  when  the  secretary  of  the  Rochdale 
Cotton-spinners  goes  to  the  quarterly  meeting  at  Manchester, 
he  need  have  no  hesitation  in  opposing  and,  if  possible, 
defeating  any  recommendation  of  the  executive  council  of 
the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners 
which  he  considers  injurious  to  the  Rochdale  spinners.  In 
the  form  of  the  representative  executive,  this  use  of  salaried 
officers  in  a  representative  capacity  is  likely  to  tend,  as  we 
have  seen,  to  the  formation  of  a  virtually  irresponsible 
governing  clique.  But  in  the  form  of  a  federal  representative 
assembly,  where  the  federal  executive  and  official  staff  are 
dependent,  not  on  the  members  at  large  but  on  the  assembly 
itself,  and  where  the  representatives  are  responsible  to  quite 
other  constituencies  and  include  a  large  proportion  of  the 
non-official  element,  this  danger  is  reduced  to  a  minimum. 

We  have  now  set  before  the  reader  an  analysis  of  the 
constitutional  development  of  Trade  Union  democracy.  The 
facts  will  be  interpreted  in  different  ways  by  students  of 
different  temperaments.  To  us  they  represent  the  long  and 
inarticulate  struggle  of  unlettered  men  to  solve  the  problem 
of  how  to  combine  administrative  efficiency  with  popular 
control.  Assent  was  the  first  requirement.  The  very 
formation  of  a  continuous  combination,  in  face  of  legal 
persecution  and  public  disapproval,  depended  on  the  active 
concurrence  of  all  the  members.  And  though  it  is  con- 
ceivable that  a  strong  Trade  Union  might  coerce  a  few 
individual  workmen  to  continue  in  its  ranks  against 
their  will,  no  such  coercive  influence  could  permanently 
prevail  over  a  discontented  majority,  or  prevent  the  secession, 
either  individually  or  in  a  body,  of  any  considerable  number 
who  were  seriously  disaffected.  It  was  accordingly  assumed 


Representative  Institutions  59 

without  question  that  everything  should  be  submitted  to 
"  the  voices "  of  the  whole  body,  and  that  each  member 
should  take  an  equal  and  identical  share  in  the  common 
project.  As  the  union  developed  from  an  angry  crowd 
unanimously  demanding  the  redress  of  a  particular  grievance 
into  an  insurance  company  of  national  extent,  obliged  to 
follow  some  definite  trade  policy,  the  need  for  administrative 
efficiency  more  and  more  forced  itself  on  the  minds  of  the 
members.  This  efficiency  involved  an  ever-increasing  special- 
isation of  function.1  The  growing  mass  of  business  and  the 
difficulty  and  complication  of  the  questions  dealt  with  involved 
the  growth  of  an  official  class,  marked  off  by  capacity,  training, 
and  habit  of  life  from  the  rank  and  file.  Failure  to  specialise 
the  executive  function  quickly  brought  about  extinction.  On 
the  other  hand  this  very  specialisation  undermined  the  popular 
control,  and  thus  risked  the  loss  of  the  indispensable  popular 
assent.  The  early  expedients  of  Rotation  of  Office,  the 
Mass  Meeting,  and  the  Referendum  proved,  in  practice,  utterly 
inadequate  as  a  means  of  securing  genuine  popular  control. 
At  each  particular  crisis  the  individual  member  found  himself 
overmatched  by  the  official  machinery  which  he  had  created. 
At  this  stage  irresponsible  bureaucracy  seemed  the  inevitable 
outcome.  But  democracy  found  yet  another  expedient,  which 
in  some  favored  unions  has  gone  far  to  solve  the  problem. 
The  specialisation  of  the  executive  into  a  permanent  expert 
civil  service  was  balanced  by  the  specialisation  of  the  legis- 
lature, in  the  establishment  of  a  supreme  representative 
assembly,  itself  undertaking  the  work  of  direction  and  control 
for  which  the  members  at  large  had  proved  incompetent. 
We  have  seen  how  difficult  it  is  for  a  community  of  manual 
workers  to  obtain  such  an  assembly,  and  how  large  a  part  is 

1  "  The  progressive  division  of  labour  by  which  both  science  and  government 
prosper." — Lord  Acton,  The  Unity  of  Modern  History  (London,  1896),  p.  3. 
"  If  there  be  one  principle  clearer  than  another,  it  is  this  :  that  in  any  business, 
whether  of  government  or  of  mere  merchandising,  somebody  must  be  trusted.  .  .  . 
Power  and  strict  accountability  for  its  use,  are  the  essential  constituents  of  good 
government." — Woodrow  Wilson,  Congressional  Government  (New  York,  1896), 
1 2th  edit. 


60  Trade  Union  Structure 

inevitably  played  in  it  by  the  ever-growing  number  of  salaried 
officers.  But  in  the  representative  assembly  these  salaried 
officers  sit  in  a  new  capacity.  The  work  expected  from  them 
by  their  employers  is  not  that  of  execution,  but  of  criticism 
and  direction.  To  balance  the  professional  civil  servant  we 
have,  in  fact,  the  professional  representative. 

This  detailed  analysis  of  humble  working-class  organisa- 
tions will  to  many  readers  be  of  interest  only  in  so  far  as  it 
furnishes  material  for  political  generalisations.  It  is  there- 
fore important  to  consider  to  what  extent  the  constitutional 
problems  of  Trade  Union  democracy  are  analogous  to  those 
of  national  or  municipal  politics. 

The  fundamental  requisites  of  government  are  the  same 
in  the  democratic  state  as  in  the  Trade  Union.  In 
both  cases  the  problem  is  how  to  combine  administrative 
efficiency  with  popular  control.  Both  alike  ultimately 
depend  on  a  continuance  of  general  assent.  In  a  voluntary 
association,  such  as  the  Trade  Union,  this  general  assent 
is,  as  we  have  seen,  the  foremost  requirement :  in  the 
democratic  state  relinquishment  of  citizenship  is  seldom  a 
practicable  alternative,  whilst  the  operation  of  changing 
governors  is  not  an  easy  one.  Hence,  even  in  the 
most  democratic  of  states  the  continuous  assent  of  the 
governed  is  not  so  imperative  a  necessity  as  in  the  Trade 
Union.  On  the  other  hand,  the  degree  of  administrative 
efficiency  necessary  for  the  healthy  existence  of  the  state  is 
far  greater  than  in  the  case  of  the  Trade  Union.  But  whilst 
admitting  this  transposition  in  relative  importance,  it  still 
remains  true  that,  in  the  democratic  state  as  in  the  Trade 
Union,  government  cannot  continue  to  exist  without  com- 
bining a  certain  degree  of  popular  assent  with  adequate 
administrative  efficiency. 

More  important  is  the  fact  that  the  popular  assent  is  in 
both  cases  of  the  same  nature.  In  the  democratic  state,  as 
in  the  Trade  Union,  the  eventual  judgment  of  the  people  is 
pronounced  not  upon  projects  but  upon  results.  It  avails 
not  that  a  particular  proposal  may  have  received  the  prior 


Representative  Institutions  61 

authorisation  of  an  express  popular  vote  ;  if  the  results  are 
not  such  as  the  people  desire,  the  executive  will  not  continue 
to  receive  their  support.  Nor  does  this,  in  the  democratic 
state  any  more  than  in  the  Trade  Union,  imply  that  an 
all-wise  government  would  necessarily  secure  this  popular 
assent.  If  any  particular  stage  in  the  march  of  civilisation 
happens  to  be  momentarily  distasteful  to  the  bulk  of  the 
citizens,  the  executive  which  ventures  to  step  in  that  direction 
will  be  no  less  ruthlessly  dismissed  than  if  its  deeds  had  been 
evil.  All  that  we  have  said  as  to  the  logical  futility  of  the 
Referendum,  and  as  to  the  necessity  for  the  representative, 
therefore  applies,  we  suggest,  even  more  strongly  to  demo- 
cratic states  than  to  Trade  Unions.  For  what  is  the  lesson 
to  be  learned  from  Trade  Union  history  ?  The  Referendum, 
introduced  for  the  express  purpose  of  ensuring  popular 
assent,  has  in  almost  all  cases  failed  to  accomplish  its  object. 
This  failure  is  due,  as  the  reader  will  have  observed,  to  the 
constant  inability  of  the  ordinary  man  to  estimate  what  will 
be  the  effect  of  a  particular  proposal.  What  Democracy 
requires  is  assent  to  results  ;  what  the  Referendum  gives  is 
assent  to  projects.  No  Trade  Union  has,  for  instance, 
deliberately  desired  bankruptcy ;  but  many  Trade  Unions 
have  persistently  voted  for  scales  of  contributions  and  benefits 
which  have  inevitably  resulted  in  bankruptcy.  If  this  is  the 
case  in  the  relatively  simple  issues  of  Trade  Union  admini- 
stration, still  more  does  it  apply  to  the  infinitely  complicated 
questions  of  national  politics. 

But  though  in  the  case  of  the  Referendum  the  analogy 
is  sufficiently  exact  to  warrant  the  transformation  of  the 
empirical  conclusions  of  Trade  Union  history  into  a  political 
generalisation,  it  is  only  fair  to  point  out  some  minor 
differences  between  the  two  cases.  We  have  had  occasion 
to  describe  how,  in  Trade  Union  history,  the  use  of  the 
Referendum,  far  from  promoting  popular  control,  has  some- 
times resulted  in  increasing  the  dominant  power  of  the 
permanent  civil  service,  and  in  making  its  position  practically 
impregnable  against  any  uprising  opinion  among  its  con- 


62  Trade  Union  Structure 

stituents.  This  particular  danger  would,  we  imagine,  scarcely 
occur  in  a  democratic  state.  In  the  Trade  Union  the 
executive  committee  occupies  a  unique  position.  It  alone 
has  access  to  official  information  ;  it  alone  commands  expert 
professional  skill  and  experience  ;  and,  most  important  of  all, 
it  monopolises  in  the  society's  official  circular  what  corre- 
sponds to  the  newspaper  press.  The  existence  of  political 
parties  fairly  equal  in  knowledge,  ability,  and  electoral 
organisation,  and  each  served  by  its  own  press,  would  always 
save  the  democratic  state  from  this  particular  perversion  of 
the  Referendum  to  the  advantage  of  the  existing  government. 
But  any  party  or  sect  of  opinion  which,  from  lack  of  funds, 
education,  or  social  influence,  could  not  call  to  its  aid  the 
forces  which  we  have  named,  would,  we  suggest,  find  itself  as 
helpless  in  face  of  a  Referendum  as  the  discontented  section 
of  a  strong  Trade  Union. 

We  have  seen,  moreover,  that  there  is  in  Trade  Union 
government  a  certain  special  class  of  questions  in  which  the 
Referendum  has  a  distinct  use.  Where  a  decision  will 
involve  at  some  future  time  the  personal  co-operation  of 
the  members  in  some  positive  act  essentially  optional  in  its 
nature — still  more  where  that  act  involves  a  voluntary 
personal  sacrifice,  or  where  not  a  majority  alone  but 
practically  the  whole  body  of  the  members  must  on  pain  of 
failure  join  in  it, — the  Referendum  may  be  useful,  not  as  a 
legislative  act,  but  as  an  index  of  the  probability  that  the 
members  will  actually  do  what  will  be  required  of  them. 
The  decision  to  strike  is  obviously  a  case  in  point.  Another 
instance  may  be  found  in  the  decisions  of  Trade  Unions 
or  other  bodies  that  each  member  shall  use  his  municipal  or 
parliamentary  franchise  in  a  particular  manner.  Here  the 
success  or  failure  of  the  policy  of  the  organisation  depends  not 
on  the  passive  acquiescence  of  the  rank  and  file  in  acts  done 
by  the  executive  committee  or  the  officers,  but  upon  each 
member's  active  performance  of  a  personal  task.  We  cannot 
think  of  any  case  of  this  kind  within  the  sphere  of  the 
modern  democratic  state.  If  indeed,  as  Mr.  Auberon  Herbert 


Representative  Institutions  63 

proposes,  it  were  left  to  the  option  of  each  citizen  to  determine 
from  time  to  time  the  amount  and  the  application  of  his 
contributions  to  the  treasury,  the  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer 
would  probably  find  it  convenient,  prior  to  making  up  the 
estimates,  to  take  a  Referendum  as  a  guide  to  how  much 
would  probably  be  paid.  Or,  to  take  an  analogy  very  near 
to  that  of  the  Trade  Union  decision  to  strike,  if  each  soldier 
in  the  army  were  at  liberty  to  leave  at  a  day's  notice,  it 
would  probably  be  found  expedient  to  take  a  vote  of  the 
rank  and  file  before  engaging  in  a  foreign  war.  In  the 
modern  democratic  state,  however,  as  it  actually  exists,  it  is 
not  left  to  the  option  of  the  individual  citizen  whether  or  not 
he  will  act  in  the  manner  decided  on.  The  success  or 
failure  of  the  policy  does  not  therefore  depend  on  obtaining 
universal  assent  and  personal  participation  in  the  act  itself. 
Whether  the  citizen  likes  it  or  not,  he  is  compelled  to  pay 
the  taxes  and  obey  the  laws  which  have  been  decided  on  by 
the  competent  authority.  Whether  or  not  he  will  maintain 
that  authority  in  power,  will  depend  not  on  his  original 
impulsive  judgment  as  to  the  expediency  of  the  tax  or  the 
law,  but  on  his  deliberate  approval  or  disapproval  of  the 
subsequent  results. 

If  Trade  Union  history  throws  doubt  on  the  advantages 
of  the  Referendum,  still  less  does  it  favor  the  institution  of 
the  delegate  as  distinguished  from  the  representative.  Even 
in  the  comparatively  simple  issues  of  Trade  Union  admini- 
stration, it  has  been  found,  in  practice,  quite  impossible  to 
obtain  definite  instructions  from  the  members  on  all  the 
matters  which  come  up  for  decision.  When,  for  instance,  the 
sixty  delegates  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers 
met  in  1892  to  revise  the  constitution  and  trade  policy  of 
their  society,  they  were  supposed  to  confine  themselves  to 
such  amendments  as  had  previously  received  the  sanction  of 
one  or  other  of  the  branches.  But  although  the  amendments 
so  sanctioned  filled  over  five  hundred  printed  pages,  it  was 
found  impossible  to  construct  from  this  material  alone  any 
consistent  constitution  or  line  of  policy.  The  delegates  were 


64  Trade  Union  Structure 

necessarily  compelled  to  exercise  larger  freedom  and  to  frame 
a  set  of  rules  not  contemplated  by  any  one  of  the  branches. 
And  this  experience  of  the  Engineers  is  only  a  type  of  what 
has  been  going  on  throughout  the  whole  Trade  Union  world. 
The  increased  facilities  for  communication,  on  the  one  hand, 
and  the  growth  of  representative  institutions,  on  the  other, 
have  made  the  delegate  obsolete.  Wherever  a  Trade  Union 
has  retained  the  old  ideal  of  direct  government  by  the  people, 
it  has  naturally  preferred  to  the  Delegate  Meeting  the  less 
expensive  and  more  thoroughgoing  device  of  the  Referendum. 
For  the  most  part  the  increasing  complication  and  intricacy 
of  modern  industrial  affairs  has,  as  we  have  seen,  compelled 
the  substitution  of  representative  institutions.  These  con- 
siderations apply  with  even  greater  force  to  the  democratic 
state. 

Trade  Union  history  gives,  therefore,  little  support  to 
the  Referendum  or  the  Delegate  Meeting,  and  points  rather 
to  government  by  a  Representative  Assembly  as  the  last 
word  of  democracy.1  It  is  therefore  important  to  see  whether 
these  Trade  Union  parliaments  have  any  lesson  for  the 
political  student.  The  governing  assemblies  of  even  the 
most  democratic  states  have,  unlike  Trade  Union  parliaments, 
hitherto  been  drawn  almost  exclusively  from  the  middle  or 
upper  classes,  and  have  therefore  escaped  the  special  difficulties 
of  communities  of  wage-earners.  If,  however,  we  assume  that 
the  manual  workers,  who  number  four-fifths  of  the  population, 
will  gradually  become  the  dominant  influence  in  the  elector- 
ate, and  will  contribute  an  important  and  increasing  section 
of  the  representatives,  the  governing  assemblies  of  the  Coal- 

1  "  There  are  two  elements  co-existent  in  the  conduct  of  human  affairs — policy 
and  administration — but,  though  the  confines  of  their  respective  jurisdictions 
overlap,  the  functions  of  each  must  of  necessity  be  exercised  within  its  own 
domain  by  its  own  hierarchy — the  one  consisting  of  trained  specialists  and 
experts,  intimately  conversant  with  the  historical  traditions  of  their  own  depart- 
ment and  with  the  minutest  details  of  the  subjects  with  which  they  are  concerned, 
the  other  qualified  by  their  large  converse  with  whatever  is  influential  and 
intelligent  in  their  own  country  or  on  the  European  Continent,  and,  above  all, 
by  their  Parliamentary  talents  and  their  tactful  appreciation  of  public  opinion,  to 
determine  the  general  lines  along  which  the  destinies  of  their  country  should  be 
led."— Speech  by  the  Marquis  of  Dufferin,  Times,  I2th  June  1897. 


Representative  Institutions  65 

miners  or  Cotton  Operatives  to-day  may  be  to  a  large  extent 
prophetic  of  the  future  legislative  assembly  in  any  English- 
speaking  community. 

One  inference  seems  to  us  clear.  Any  effective  participa- 
tion of  the  wage-earning  class  in  the  councils  of  the  nation 
involves  the  establishment  of  a  new  calling,  that  of  the 
professional  representative.  For  the  parish  or  town  council 
it  is  possible  to  elect  men  who  will  continue  to  work 
at  their  trades,  just  as  a  Trade  Union  branch  can  be 
administered  by  committee-men  and  officers  in  full  work. 
The  adoption  of  the  usual  Co-operative  and  Trade  Union 
practice  of  paying  travelling  expenses  and  an  allowance  for 
the  actual  time  spent  on  the  public  business  would  suffice 
to  enable  workmen  to  attend  the  district  or  county  council. 
But  the  governing  assembly  of  any  important  state  must 
always  demand  practically  the  whole  time  of  its  members. 
The  working-man  representative  in  the  House  of  Commons 
is  therefore  most  closely  analogous,  not  to  the  working  miner 
or  spinner  who  attends  the  Coal  or  Cotton  Parliament,  but 
to  the  permanent  and  salaried  official  representatives,  who, 
in  both  these  assemblies,  exercise  the  predominant  influence 
and  control  the  executive  work.  The  analogy  may  therefore 
seem  to  point  to  the  election  to  the  House  of  Commons  of 
the  trained  representative  who  has  been  successful  in  the 
parliament  of  his  trade. 

Such  a  suggestion  misses  the  whole  moral  of  Trade 
Union  history.  The  cotton  or  coal -mining  official  repre- 
sentative succeeds  in  influencing  his  own  trade  assembly 
because  he  has  mastered  the  technical  details  of  all  the 
business  that  comes  before  it ;  because  his  whole  life  has 
been  one  long  training  for  the  duties  which  he  has  to 
discharge  ;  because,  in  short,  he  has  become  a  professional 
expert  in  ascertaining  and  representing  the  desires  of  his 
constituents  and  in  bringing  about  the  conditions  of  their 
fulfilment.  But  transport  this  man  to  the  House  of 
Commons,  and  he  finds  himself  confronted  with  facts  and 
problems  as  foreign  to  his  experience  and  training  as  his 
VOL.  i  F 


66  Trade  Union  Structure 

own  business  would  be  to  the  banker  or  the  country  gentle- 
man. What  the  working  class  will  presently  recognise  is 
that  the  duties  of  a  parliamentary  representative  constitute 
as  much  a  new  business  to  the  Trade  Union  official  as  the 
duties  of  a  general  secretary  are  to  the  ordinary  mechanic. 
When  workmen  desire  to  be  as  efficiently  represented  in 
the  Parliament  of  the  nation  as  they  are  in  their  own 
trade  assemblies,  they  will  find  themselves  compelled  to 
establish  a  class  of  expert  parliamentary  representatives, 
just  as  they  have  had  to  establish  a  class  of  expert  trade 
officials. 

We  need  not  consider  in  any  detail  what  effect  an  influx 
of  "  labor  members  "  of  this  new  type  would  probably  have 
upon  the  British  House  of  Commons.  Any  one  who  has 
watched  the  deliberations  of  the  Coal  or  the  Cotton  Parlia- 
ment, or  the  periodical  revising  committees  of  the  other 
great  unions,  will  have  been  impressed  by  the  disinclination 
of  the  professional  representative  to  mere  talk,  his  impatience 
of  dilatory  procedure,  and  his  determination  to  "get  the 
business  through"  within  working  hours.  Short  speeches, 
rigorous  closure,  and  an  almost  extravagant  substitution 
of  printed  matter  for  lengthy  "  front  bench "  explanations 
render  these  assemblies  among  the  most  efficient  of  demo- 
cratic bodies.1 

More  important  is  it  to  consider  in  what  respects, 
judging  from  Trade  Union  analogies,  the  expert  professional 
representative  will  differ  from  the  unpaid  politician  to  whom 
the  middle  and  upper  classes  have  hitherto  been  accustomed. 
We  have  already  described  how  in  the  Trade  Union  world 
the  representative  has  a  twofold  function,  neither  part  of 
which  may  be  neglected  with  impunity.  He  makes  it  just 
as  much  his  business  to  ascertain  and  express  the  real 
desires  of  his  constituents  as  he  does  to  control  and  direct 
the  operations  of  the  civil  servants  of  his  trade.  With  the 

1  These  representative  assemblies  present  a  great  contrast  to  the  Trade 
Union  Congress,  as  to  which  see  the  subsequent  chapter  on  "The  Method  of 
Legal  Enactment." 


Representative  Institutions  67 

entrance  into  the  House  of  Commons  of  men  of  this  type, 
the  work  of  ascertaining  and  expressing  the  wishes  of  the 
constituencies  would  be  much  more  deliberately  pursued 
than  at  present.  The  typical  member  of  Parliament  to-day 
attends  to  such  actual  expressions  of  opinion  as  reach  him 
from  his  constituency  in  a  clear  and  definite  form,  but 
regards  it  as  no  part  of  his  work  actively  to  discover  what 
the  silent  or  inarticulate  electors  are  vaguely  desiring.  He 
visits  his  constituency  at  rare  intervals,  and  then  only  to 
expound  his  own  views  in  set  speeches  at  public  meetings, 
whilst  his  personal  intercourse  is  almost  entirely  limited 
to  persons  of  his  own  class  or  to  political  wire-pullers. 
Whatever  may  be  his  intentions,  he  is  seldom  in  touch 
with  any  but  the  middle  or  upper  class,  together  with 
that  tiny  section  of  all  classes  to  whom  "  politics "  is  of 
constant  interest.  Of  the  actual  grievances  and  "  dim  in- 
articulate" aspirations  of  the  bulk  of  the  people,  the  lower 
middle  and  the  wage-earning  class,  he  has  practically  no 
conception.  When  representation  of  working-class  opinion 
becomes  a  profession,  as  in  the  Trade  Union  world,  we  see 
a  complete  revolution  in  the  attitude  of  the  representative 
towards  his  constituents.  To  find  out  what  his  constituents 
desire  becomes  an  essential  part  of  his  work.  It  will  not  do 
to  wait  until  they  write  to  him,  for  the  working-man  is  slow 
to  put  pen  to  paper.  Hence  the  professional  Trade  Union 
representative  takes  active  steps  to  learn  what  the  silent 
members  are  thinking.  He  spends  his  whole  time,  when 
not  actually  in  session,  in  his  constituency.  He  makes  few 
set  speeches  at  public  gatherings,  but  he  is  diligent  in 
attending  branch  meetings,  and  becomes  an  attentive  listener 
at  local  committees.  At  his  office  he  is  accessible  to  every 
one  of  his  constituents.  It  is,  moreover,  part  of  the  regular 
routine  of  such  a  functionary  to  be  constantly  communicat- 
ing with  every  one  of  his  constituents  by  means  of  frequent 
circulars  on  points  which  he  believes  to  be  of  special  interest 
to  them.  If,  therefore,  the  professional  representative,  as  we 
know  him  in  the  Trade  Union  world,  becomes  a  feature  of 


68  Trade  Union  Structure 

the  House  of  Commons,  the  future  member  of  Parliament 
will  feel  himself  not  only  the  authoritative  exponent  of 
the  votes  of  his  constituents,  but  also  their  "  London 
Correspondent,"  their  parliamentary  agent,  and  their 
expert  adviser  in  all  matters  of  legislation  or  general 
politics.1 

It  is  impossible  to  forecast  all  the  consequences  that 
would  follow  from  raising  (or,  as  some  would  say,  degrading) 
the  parliamentary  representative  from  an  amateur  to  a  pro- 
fessional. But  among  other  things  the  whole  etiquette  of 
the  situation  would  be  changed.  At  present  it  is  a  point 
of  honor  in  a  member  of  Parliament  not  to  express  his 
constituents'  desires  when  he  conscientiously  differs  from 
them.  To  the  "  gentleman  politician  "  the  only  alternative 
to  voting  as  he  himself  thinks  best  is  resigning  his  seat. 
This  delicacy  is  unknown  to  any  paid  professional  agent. 
The  architect,  solicitor,  or  permanent  civil  servant,  after 
tendering  his  advice  and  supporting  his  views  with  all  his 
expert  authority,  finally  carries  out  whatever  policy  his 
employer  commands.  This  is  also  the  view  which  the 
professional  representative  of  the  Trade  Union  world  takes 
of  his  own  duties.  It  is  his  business  not  only  to  put  before 
his  constituents  what  he  believes  to  be  their  best  policy  and 
to  back  up  his  opinion  with  all  the  argumentative  power  he 
can  bring  to  bear,  but  also  to  put  his  entire  energy  into 
wrestling  with  what  he  conceives  to  be  their  ignorance,  and 
to  become  for  the  time  a  vigorous  propagandist  of  his  own 
policy.  But  if,  when  he  has  done  his  best  in  this  way,  he 
fails  to  get  a  majority  over  to  his  view,  he  loyally  accepts 
the  decision  and  records  his  vote  in  accordance  with  his 
constituents'  desires.  We  imagine  that  professional  repre- 
sentatives of  working-class  opinion  in  the  House  of  Commons 
would  take  the  same  course.2 

1  "  Representatives  ought  to  give  light  and  leading  to  the  people,  just  as  the 
people  give  stimulus  and  momentum  to  their  representatives." — J.  Bryce,  The 
American  Commonwealth  (London,  1891),  vol.  i.  p.  297. 

2  It  is  interesting  to  notice  that  in  the  country  in  which  the  "sovereignty  of 


Representative  Institutions  69 

This  may  at  first  seem  to  indicate  a  return  of  the  pro- 
fessional representative  to  the  position  of  a  delegate.  Trade 
Union  experience  points,  however,  to  the  very  reverse.  In  the 
great  majority  of  cases  a  constituency  cannot  be  said  to  have 
any  clear  and  decided  views  on  particular  projects.  What 
they  ask  from  their  representative  is  that  he  shall  act  in  the 
manner  which,  in  his  opinion,  will  best  serve  to  promote 
their  general  desires.  It  is  only  in  particular  instances, 
usually  when  some  well-intentioned  proposal  entails  im- 
mediately inconvenient  results,  that  a  wave  of  decided 
opinion  spreads  through  a  working-class  constituency.  It 
is  exactly  in  cases  of  this  kind  that  a  propagandist  campaign 
by  a  professional  debater,  equipped  with  all  the  facts,  is  of 
the  greatest  utility.  Such  a  campaign  would  be  the  very 
last  thing  that  a  member  of  Parliament  of  the  present  type 
would  venture  upon  if  he  thought  that  his  constituents  were 
against  him.  He  would  feel  that  the  less  the  points  of 
difference  were  made  prominent,  the  better  for  his  own 
safety.  But  once  it  came  to  be  understood  that  the  final 
command  of  the  constituency  would  be  obeyed,  the  repre- 
sentative would  run  no  risk  of  losing  his  seat,  merely  because 
he  did  his  best  to  convert  his  constituents.  Judging  from 
Trade  Union  experience  he  would,  in  nine  cases  out  of  ten, 
succeed  in  converting  them  to  his  own  view,  and  thus 
perform  a  valuable  piece  of  political  education.  In  the 
tenth  case  the  campaign  would  have  been  no  less  educa- 
tional, though  in  another  way ;  and,  whichever  was  the 
right  view,  the  issue  would  have  been  made  clear,  the  facts 
brought  out,  and  the  way  opened  for  the  eventual  conversion 
of  one  or  other  of  the  contending  parties. 

Trade  Union  experience  indicates,  therefore,  a  still  further 
development  in  the  evolution  of  the  representative.  Working- 

the  people  "  has  been  most  whole-heartedly  accepted,  the  Trade  Union  practice 
prevails.  The  members  of  the  Swiss  "  Bundesrath  "  (Federal  Cabinet)  do  not 
resign  when  any  project  is  disapproved  of  by  the  legislature,  nor  do  the  members 
of  the  "  Nationalrath  "  throw  up  their  legislative  functions  when  a  measure  is 
rejected  by  the  electors  on  Referendum.  Both  cabinet  ministers  and  legislators 
set  themselves  to  carry  out  the  popular  will. 


70  Trade  Union  Structure 

class  democracy  will  expect  him  not  only  to  be  able  to 
understand  and  interpret  the  desires  of  his  electors,  and 
effectively  to  direct  and  control  the  administrating  executive  : 
he  must  also  count  it  as  part  of  his  duty  to  be  the  expert 
parliamentary  adviser  of  his  constituency,  and  at  times  an 
active  propagandist  of  his  own  advice.  Thus,  if  any  inference 
from  Trade  Union  history  is  valid  in  the  larger  sphere,  the 
whole  tendency  of  working-class  democracy  will  unconsciously 
be  to  exalt  the  real  power  of  the  representative,  and  more 
and  more  to  differentiate  his  functions  from  those  of  the 
ordinary  citizen  on  the  one  hand,  and  of  the  expert  admini- 
strator on  the  other.  The  typical  representative  assembly  of 
the  future  will,  it  may  be  suggested,  be  as  far  removed  from 
the  House  of  Commons  of  to-day  as  the  latter  is  from  the 
mere  Delegate  Meeting.  We  have  already  travelled  far  from 
the  one  man  taken  by  rotation  from  the  roll,  and  changed 
mechanically  to  convey  "  the  voices  "  of  the  whole  body.  We 
may  in  the  future  leave  equally  behind  the  member  to  whom 
wealth,  position,  or  notoriety  secures,  almost  by  accident,  a 
seat  in  Parliament,  in  which  he  can,  in  such  intervals  as  his 
business  or  pleasure  may  leave  him,  decide  what  he  thinks 
best  for  the  nation.  In  his  stead  we  may  watch  appearing  in 
increasing  numbers  the  professional  representative, — a  man 
selected  for  natural  aptitude,  deliberately  trained  for  his  new 
work  as  a  special  vocation,  devoting  his  whole  time  to  the 
discharge  of  his  manifold  duties,  and  actively  maintaining 
an  intimate  and  reciprocal  intellectual  relationship  with  his 
constituency. 

How  far  such  a  development  of  the  representative  will 
fit  in  with  the  party  system  as  we  now  know  it ;  how  far  it 
will  increase  the  permanence  and  continuity  of  parliamentary 
life ;  how  far  it  will  promote  collective  action  and  tend  to 
increasing  bureaucracy ;  how  far,  on  the  other  hand,  it  will 
bring  the  ordinary  man  into  active  political  citizenship,  and 
rehabilitate  the  House  of  Commons  in  popular  estimation  ; 
how  far,  therefore,  it  will  increase  the  real  authority  of  the 
people  over  the  representative  assembly,  and  of  the  repre- 


Representative  Institutions  71 

sentative  assembly  over  the  permanent  civil  service  ;  how  far, 
in  fine,  it  will  give  us  that  combination  of  administrative 
efficiency  with  popular  control  which  is  at  once  the  requisite 
and  the  ideal  of  all  democracy — all  these  are  questions  that 
make  the  future  interesting. 


CHAPTER    III 

THE    UNIT    OF    GOVERNMENT 

TPIE  trade  clubs  of  the  eighteenth  century  inherited  from 
the  Middle  Ages  the  tradition  of  strictly  localised  corpora- 
tions, the  unit  of  government  necessarily  coinciding,  like  that 
of  the  English  craft  gild,  with  the  area  of  the  particular  city 
in  which  the  members  lived.  And  we  can  well  imagine  that 
a  contemporary  observer  of  the  constitution  and  policy  of 
these  little  democracies  might  confidently  have  predicted  that 
they,  like  the  craft  gilds,  must  inevitably  remain  strictly 
localised  bodies.  The  crude  and  primitive  form  of  popular 
government  to  which,  as  we  have  seen,  the  workmen  were 
obstinately  devoted,  could  only  serve  the  needs  of  a  small 
and  local  society.  Government  by  general  meeting  of  all 
the  members,  administration  by  the  forced  service  of  indi- 
viduals taken  in  rotation  from  the  roll — in  short,  the  ideal 
of  each  member  taking  an  equal  and  identical  share  in  the 
management  of  public  affairs — was  manifestly  impracticable 
in  any  but  a  society  of  which  the  members  met  each  other 
with  the  frequent  intimacy  of  near  neighbours.  Yet  in  spite 
of  all  difficulties  of  constitutional  machinery,  the  historian 
watches  these  local  trade  clubs,  in  marked  contrast  with  the 
craft  gilds,  irresistibly  expanding  into  associations  of  national 
extent.  Thus,  the  little  friendly  club  which  twenty -three 
Bolton  ironfounders  established  in  1809  spread  steadily  over 
the  whole  of  England,  Ireland,  and  Wales,  until  to-day  it 
numbers  over  16,000  members,  dispersed  among  122  separate 


The  Unit  of  Government  73 

branches.  The  scores  of  little  clubs  of  millwrights  and 
steam-engine  makers,  fitters  and  blacksmiths,  as  if  impelled 
by  some  overmastering  impulse,  drew  together  between  1 840 
and  1851  to  form  the  great  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Engineers.  The  Amalgamated  Society  of  Carpenters  and 
Joiners  (established  1860)  has,  in  the  thirty-five  years  of  its 
existence,  absorbed  several  dozens  of  local  carpenters'  societies, 
and  now  counts  within  its  ranks  four-fifths  of  the  organised 
carpenters  in  the  kingdom.  Finally,  we  see  organisations 
established,  like  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Railway 
Servants  in  1872,  with  the  deliberate  intention  of  covering 
the  whole  trade  from  one  end  of  the  kingdom  to  the  other. 
How  slowly,  painfully,  and  reluctantly  the  workmen  have 
modified  their  crude  ideas  of  democracy  to  meet  the  exigencies 
of  a  national  organisation,  we  have  already  described. 

But  it  was  not  merely  the  workman's  simplicity  in  matters 
of  government  that  hampered  the  growth  of  national  organisa- 
tion. The  traditional  policy  of  the  craftsman  of  the  English 
town — the  restriction  of  the  right  to  work  to  those  who  had 
acquired  the  "  freedom  "  of  the  corporation,  the  determined 
exclusion  of  "  interlopers,"  and  the  craving  to  keep  trade 
from  going  out  of  the  town — has  left  deep  roots  in  English 
industrial  life,  alike  among  the  shopkeepers  and  among  the 
workmen.  Trade  Unionism  has  had  constantly  to  struggle 
against  this  spirit  of  local  monopoly,  specially  noticeable  in 
the  seaport  towns.1 

Down  to  the  middle  of  the  present  century  the  ship- 
wrights had  an  independent  local  club  in  every  port,  each  of 
which  strove  with  might  and  main  to  exclude  from  any 
chance  of  work  in  the  port  all  but  men  who  had  learnt  their 
trade  within  its  bounds.  These  monopoly  rules  caused 
incessant  friction  between  the  men  of  the  several  ports. 
Shipwrights  out  of  work  in  one  town  could  not  perma- 
nently be  kept  away  from  another  in  which  more  hands  were 

1  It  is  interesting  to  note  that  the  modern  forms  of  the  monopoly  spirit  are 
also  specially  characteristic  of  the  industry  of  shipbuilding ;  see  the  chapter  on 
"  The  Right  to  a  Trade." 


74  Trade  Union  Structure 

wanted.  The  newcomers,  refused  admission  into  the  old  port 
society,  eventually  formed  a  new  local  union  among  them- 
selves, and  naturally  tended  to  ignore  the  trade  regulations 
maintained  by  the  monopolists.  To  remedy  this  disastrous 
state  of  things  a  loose  federation  was  between  1850  and 
1860  gradually  formed  among  the  local  societies  for  the 
express  purpose  of  discussing,  at  annual  congresses,  how  to 
establish  more  satisfactory  relations  between  the  ports.  In 
the  records  of  these  congresses  we  watch,  for  nearly  thirty 
years,  the  struggle  of  the  monopolist  societies  against  the 
efforts  of  those,  such  as  Glasgow  and  Newcastle,  whose 
circumstances  had  converted  them  to  a  belief  in  complete 
mobility  of  labor  within  a  trade.  The  open  societies 
at  last  lost  patience  with  the  conservative  spirit  of  the 
others,  and  in  1882  united  to  form  a  national  amalgamated 
union,  based  on  the  principle  of  a  common  purse  and 
complete  mobility  between  port  and  port.  This  organisa- 
tion, the  Associated  Shipwrights'  Society,  has,  in  fifteen 
years,  succeeded  in  absorbing  all  but  three  of  the  local 
societies,  and  now  extends  to  every  port  in  the  kingdom. 
"  In  these  times  of  mammoth  firms,  with  large  capital,"  writes 
the  general  secretary,  "  the  days  of  local  societies'  utility  have 
gone  by,  and  it  is  to  be  hoped  the  few  still  remaining  outside 
the  consolidated  association  of  their  trade  will  ere  long  lay 
aside  all  local  animus  and  trivial  objections,  or  personal 
feeling  ...  for  the  paramount  interest  of  their  trade."  l 

The  history  of  the  Shipwrights'  organisation  is  typical 
of  that  of  other  port  unions.  The  numerous  societies  of 
Sailmakers,  once  rigidly  monopolist,  are  now  united  in  a 
federation,  within  which  complete  mobility  prevails.'2  The 
Coopers'  societies,  which  in  the  port  towns  had  formerly 
much  in  common  with  the  Shipwrights,  now,  with  one  excep- 
tion, admit  to  membership  any  duly  apprenticed  cooper  from 

1  Twelfth  Annual  Report  of  Associated  Shipwrights'  Society  (Newcastle,  1 894), 
p.  xi. 

2  Rules  for  the  Guidance  of  the  Federation  of  the  Sailmakers  of  Great  Britain 
and  Ireland  (Hull,  1890). 


The  Unit  of  Government  75 

another  town.  But  the  main  citadels  of  local  monopoly 
in  the  Trade  Union  world  have  always  been  the  trade  clubs 
of  Dublin,  Cork,  and  Limerick.  The  Dublin  Coopers  have, 
even  at  the  present  time,  a  rigidly  closed  society,  which 
refuses  all  intercourse  with  other  unions,  and  maintains, 
through  an  ingenious  arrangement,  a  strict  monopoly  of  this 
important  coopering  centre  j1  and  the  Cork  Stonemasons, 
who  are  combined  in  an  old  local  club,  whilst  insisting  on 
working  at  Fermoy  whenever  they  please,  will  not,  as  we 
learn,  suffer  any  mason,  from  Fermoy  or  elsewhere,  to  obtain 
employment  at  Cork. 

Even  in  Ireland,  however,  the  development  of  Trade 
Unionism  is  hostile  to  local  monopoly.  Any  growing  in- 
dustry is  quickly  invaded  by  members  of  the  great  English 
societies,  who  establish  their  own  branches  and  force  the 
local  clubs  to  come  to  terms.  One  by  one  old  Irish  unions 
apply  to  be  admitted  as  branches  into  the  richer  and  more 
powerful  English  societies,  and  have  in  consequence  to  accept 
the  principle  of  complete  mobility  of  labor.  The  famous 

1  The  arrangement  is  as  follows :  The  Dublin  Coopers  do  not  prohibit 
strangers  from  working  in  Dublin  when  more  coopers  are  wanted.  On  such 
occasions  the  secretary  writes  to  coopers'  societies  in  other  towns,  notably  Burton, 
stating  the  number  of  men  required.  Upon  all  such  outsiders  a  tax  of  a  shilling 
a  week  is  levied  as  "  working  fee,"  half  of  which  benefits  the  Dublin  society,  the 
other  half  being  accumulated  to  pay  the  immigrant's  return  fare.  As  soon  as 
work  shows  signs  of  approaching  slackness,  the  "foreigner"  receives  warning 
that  he  must  instantly  depart :  it  is  said  that  his  return  ticket  is  presented  to  him, 
with  any  balance  remaining  out  of  his  weekly  sixpence.  As  many  as  200 
"  strangers  "  will  in  this  way  sometimes  be  paid  off,  and  sent  away  in  a  single 
week.  By  this  means  the  Dublin  Coopers  (a)  secure  absolute  regularity  of 
employment  for  their  own  members,  (b]  provide  the  extra  labor  required  in  busy 
times,  and  (c)  maintain  their  own  control  over  the  conditions  under  which  the 
work  is  done.  The  employers  appear  to  be  satisfied  with  the  arrangement,  which, 
so  far  as  we  have  been  able  to  ascertain,  is  the  only  surviving  instance  of  what 
was  once  a  common  rule  of  port  unions.  Thus,  the  rules  of  Queenstown  Ship- 
wrights' Society,  right  down  to  its  absorption  in  the  Associated  Shipwrights' 
Society  (in  1894),  included  a  provision  that  "no  strange  shipwright"  should  be 
allowed  to  work  in  the  town  while  a  member  was  idle.  And  the  Liverpool 
Sailmakers'  Society  (established  1817)  has,  among  the  MS.  rules  preserved  in  the 
old  minute-book,  one  providing  that  "strangers"  with  indentures  should  be 
allowed  to  work  at  "legal  sail-rooms,"  but  should  members  be  unable  to  obtain 
employment  elsewhere,  then  "  the  stranger  shall  be  discharged  and  the  member  be 
engaged." 


76  Trade  Union  Structure 

"  Dublin  Regulars,"  a  rigidly  monopolist  local  carpenters' 
union,  claiming  descent  from  the  gilds,  and  always  striving 
to  exclude  from  admission  any  but  the  sons  of  the  members,1 
became,  in  1890,  at  the  instance  of  its  younger  members,  one 
of  the  629  branches  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Car- 
penters and  Joiners,  bound  to  admit  to  work  fellow-members 
from  all  parts  of  the  world.  Among  the  Irish  Shipwrights, 
too,  once  the  most  rigidly  monopolist  of  all,  this  tendency 
has  progressed  with  exceptional  rapidity.  The  annual  report 
of  the  Associated  Shipwrights'  Society  for  1893  records2 
the  absorption  in  that  year  alone  of  no  fewer  than  six  old 
Irish  port  unions,  each  of  which  had  hitherto  striven  to 
maintain  for  its  members  all  the  work  of  its  own  port. 

But  although  the  growth  of  national  organisation  has 
done  much  to  break  down  this  spirit  of  local  monopoly, 
we  do  not  wish  to  imply  that  it  has  been  completely 
eradicated.  The  workman,  whether  a  Trade  Unionist  or 
not,  still  shares  with  the  shopkeeper  and  the  small  manu- 
facturer, the  old  instinctive  objection  to  work  "going  out 
of  the  town."  The  proceedings  of  local  authorities  often 
reveal  to  us  the  "  small  master,"  the  retail  tradesman, 
and  the  local  artisan  all  insisting  that  "  the  ratepayers' 
money "  should  be  spent  so  as  directly  to  benefit  the  local 
trade.  Trade  Unionists  are  not  backward  in  making  use 
of  this  vulgar  error  when  it  suits  their  purpose,  and  the 
"  labor  members "  of  town  or  county  councils  can  seldom 
refrain,  whenever  it  is  proposed  "to  send  work  into  the 
country,"  from  adopting  an  argument  which  they  find  so 
convincing  to  many  of  their  middle-class  colleagues.8 

1  See,  for  instance,  the  detailed  account  of  it  given  in  the  Report  on  Trade 
Societies  and  Strikes  of  the  National  Association  for  the  Promotion  of  Social  Science 
(1860),  pp.  418-423. 

2  Tivelfth  Annual  Report  of  the  Associated  Shipwrights'  Society,  p.  xi.  (New- 
castle, 1894). 

3  During  the  first  eight  years  of  the  London  County  Council  (1889-97)  several 
attempts  were  made  to  confine  contracts  to  London  firms.      It  is  interesting  to 
note  that  these  all  emanated  from  middle-class  members  of  the  Moderate  Party,  and 
that   they  were  opposed    by  John  Burns  and  a  large  majority  of  the  "  Labor 
Members  "  and  Progressives,  as  well  as  by  the  more  responsible  of  the  "  Moderates." 


The  Unit  of  Government  77 

But  if  we  follow  the  Labor  Member  from  the  council 
chamber  to  his  Trade  Union  branch  meeting,  we  shall 
recognise  that  the  grievance  felt  by  his  Trade  Unionist 
constituents  is  not  exclusively,  or  even  mainly,  based  on 
the  "  local  protectionism  "  of  the  shopkeeper  and  the  small 
manufacturer.  What  the  urban  Trade  Unionist  actually 
resists  is  not  any  loss  of  work  to  a  particular  locality,  but 
the  incessant  attempt  of  contractors  to  evade  the  Trade 
Union  regulations,  by  getting  the  work  done  in  districts  in 
which  the  workmen  are  either  not  organised  at  all,  or  in 
which  they  are  working  at  a  low  Standard  Rate.  Thus  the 
Friendly  Society  of  Operative  Stonemasons  incurs  consider- 
able odium  because  the  branches  in  many  large  towns  insert 
in  their  local  rules  a  prohibition  of  the  use  of  stone  imported 
in  a  worked  state  from  any  outside  district.  But  this  general 
prohibition  arises  from  the  fact  that  the  practical  alternative 
to  working  the  stone  on  the  spot  is  getting  it  worked  in  the 
district  in  which  it  is  quarried.  Now,  whatever  mechanical 
or  economic  advantage  may  be  claimed  for  the  latter 
practice,  it  so  happens  that  the  quarry  districts  are  those 
in  which  the  Stonemasons  are  worst  organised.  In  these 
districts  for  the  most  part,  no  Standard  Rate  exists,  the 
hours  of  labor  are  long  and  variable,  and  competitive  piece- 
work, unregulated  by  any  common  agreement,  usually  prevails. 
Moreover,  any  transference  of  work  from  the  Stonemasons 
of  large  cities  where  jobs  dovetail  with  each  other,  to  the 
Stonemasons  of  quarry  villages,  entirely  dependent  on  the 
spasmodic  orders  for  worked  stone  received  by  the  quarry 
>wner,  necessarily  involves  an  increase  in  the  number  of 
Stonemasons  exposed  to  irregularity  of  work,  and  habitually 
on  tramp  "  from  county  to  county.1 

1  For  instance  the  "Working  Rules  to  be  observed  by  the  Master  Builders 
and  Operative  Stonemasons  of  Portsmouth,"  signed  in  1893,  by  ten  master 
builders  and  four  workmen,  on  behalf  of  their  respective  associations,  include  the 
following  provision,  "  That  no  piecework  be  allowed  and  no  worked  stone  to 
come  into  the  town  except  square  steps,  flags,  curbs,  and  landings,  and  no  brick- 
'  yers  to  fix  worked  stone."  The  London  rules  are  not  so  explicit.  As  formally 
jreed  to  in  \  893  by  the  associations  of  employers  and  employed,  they  provide 


78  Trade  Union  Structure 

We  may  trace  a  similar  feeling  in  the  protests  frequently 
made  by  the  branches  of  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and 
Shoe  Operatives,  against  work  being  sent  into  the  country 
villages,  or  even  from  a  centre  in  which  wages  are  high,  to 
one  working  under  a  lower  "  statement."  That  this  is  not 
merely  a  disguised  "  local  protectionism  "  may  be  seen  from 
the  fact  that  the  Northampton  Branch  actually  resolved  in 
1888  to  strike,  not  against  Northampton  employers  sending 
work  out  of  the  town,  but  against  a  London  manufacturer 
sending  his  work  to  Northampton.1  In  1889,  the  Executive 
Council  of  the  same  union  found  itself  driven  to  take  action 
against  the  systematic  attempts  of  certain  employers  to 
evade  the  wages  agreement  which  they  had  formally  entered 
into,  by  sending  their  work  away  to  have  certain  processes 

that  "  piecework  and  subcontracting  for  labor  only  shall  on  no  account  be  resorted 
to,  excepting  for  granite  kerb,  York  paving  and  turning."  The  London  Stone- 
masons, however,  claim,  as  for  instance  in  their  complaint  in  1894  against  the 
Works  Department  of  the  London  County  Council,  that  this  rule  must  be 
interpreted  so  as  to  exclude  the  use  in  London  of  stone  worked  in  a  quarry 
district.  This  claim  was  successfully  resisted  by  the  Trade  Union  repre- 
sentatives who  sat  on  the  Works  Committee.  We  subsequently  investigated 
this  case  ourselves,  tracing  the  stone  (a  long  run  of  sandstone  kerb  for  park 
railings)  back  to  Derbyshire,  where  it  was  quarried  and  worked.  We  found  the 
district  totally  unorganised,  the  stonemasons'  work  being  done  largely  by  boy- 
labor,  at  competitive  piecework,  without  settled  agreement,  by  non-unionists, 
working  irregular  and  sometimes  excessive  hours.  It  was  impossible  not  to  feel 
that,  although  the  London  Stonemasons  had  expressed  their  objection  in  the 
wrong  terms  and  therefore  had  failed  to  obtain  redress,  they  were,  according 
to  the  "  Fair  Wages "  policy  adopted  by  the  County  Council  and  the  House 
of  Commons,  justified  in  their  complaint.  Unfortunately,  instead  of  bringing 
to  the  notice  of  the  Committee  the  actual  conditions  under  which  the  stone 
was  being  worked,  they  relied  on  the  argument  that  the  London  ratepayers' 
money  should  be  spent  on  London  workmen.  This  argument,  as  they  afterwards 
explained  to  us,  had  been  found  the  most  effective  with  the  shopkeepers  and 
small  manufacturers  who  dominate  provincial  Town  Councils.  The  Trade 
Unionist  members  of  the  London  County  Council  proved  obdurate  to  this 
economic  heresy. 

1  Shoe  and  Leather  Record,  28th  July  1888.  In  the  same  way  a  general 
meeting  of  the  Manchester  Stonemasons,  in  1862,  decided  to  support  a  strike- 
against  a  Manchester  employer  who,  carrying  out  a  contract  at  Altrincham,  eight 
miles  off,  had  his  stone  worked  at  Manchester,  instead  of  at  Altrincham,  as 
required  by  the  working  rules  of  the  Altrincham  branch.  In  this  case,  the 
Manchester  Stonemasons  struck  against  work  coming  to  themselves  at  a  higher 
rate  per  hour  than  was  demanded  by  the  Altrincham  masons. — Stonemasons' 
Fortnightly  Return^  September  1862. 


The  Unit  of  Government  79 

done  in  lower  -  paid  districts.  These  employers  were 
accordingly  informed,  not  that  the  work  must  be  kept  in 
the  town,  but  that,  wherever  it  was  executed,  the  "shop 
statement "  which  they  had  signed  must  be  adhered  to.  It 
was  at  the  same  time  expressly  intimated  that  if  these 
employers  chose  to  set  up  works  of  their  own  in  a  new 
place,  "  they  will  be  at  perfect  liberty  to  do  so,"  without 
objection  from  the  union,  even  if  they  chose  a  low-paid 
district,  "  provided  that  they  pay  the  highest  rate  of  wages 
of  the  district  to  which  they  go."  l 

We  have  quoted  the  strongest  instances  of  Trade  Union 
objection  to  "  work  going  out  of  the  town,"  in  order  to 
unravel,  from  the  common  stock  of  economic  prejudice,  the 
impulse  which  is  distinctive  of  Trade  Unionism  itself.  It  is 
customary  for  persons  interested  in  the  prosperity  of  one 
establishment,  one  town  or  one  district,  to  seek  to  obtain 
trade  for  that  particular  establishment,  town  or  district. 
Had  Trade  Unions  remained,  like  the  mediaeval  craft  gilds, 
organisations  of  strictly  local  membership,  they  must,  almost 
inevitably,  have  been  marked  by  a  similar  local  favoritism. 
But  the  whole  tendency  of  Trade  Union  history  has  been 
towards  the  solidarity  of  each  trade  as  a  whole.  The 
natural  selfishness  of  the  local  branches  is  accordingly  always 
being  combated  by  the  central  executives  and  national 
delegate  meetings,  in  the  wider  interests  of  the  whole  body 
of  the  members  wherever  they  may  be  working.  Just  in 
proportion  as  Trade  Unionism  is  strong  and  well  established 
we  find  the  old  customary  favoritism  of  locality  replaced 
by  the  impartial  enforcement  of  uniform  conditions  upon 
all  districts  alike.  When,  for  instance,  the  Amalgamated 
Association  of  Cotton  Weavers,  in  delegate  meeting  assembled, 
finally  decided  to  adopt  a  uniform  list  of  piecework  prices, 
the  members  then  working  at  Great  Harwood  found  no 
sympathy  for  their  plea  that  such  a  measure  would  reduce 

1  The  "National  Conference"  of  the  Union  passed  a  similar  resolution  in 
1886;  Monthly  Report  of  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives, 
January  1887  and  February  1889. 


80  Trade  Union  Structure 

their  own  exceptionally  high  rates.  And  although  it  was 
foreseen  and  declared  that  uniformity  would  tend  to  the 
concentration  of  the  manufacture  in  the  most  favorably 
situated  districts,  to  the  consequent  loss  of  the  more  remote 
villages,  the  delegates  from  these  villages  almost  unanimously 
supported  what  was  believed  to  be  good  for  the  trade  as  a 
whole.1 

In  another  industry,  the  contrast  between  the  old  "  local 
protectionism  "  and  the  Trade  Unionist  view  has  resulted  in 
an  interesting  change  in  electioneering  tactics.  The  London 
Society  of  Compositors  and  the  Typographical  Association 
have,  for  the  last  ten  years,  used  more  electoral  pressure  with 
regard  to  the  distribution  of  local  work,  than  any  other  Trade 
Union.  So  long  as  parliamentary  electors  belonged  mainly  to 
the  middle  class,  a  parliamentary  candidate  was  advised  by  his 
agent  to  distribute  his  large  printing  orders  fairly  among  all 
parts  of  his  constituency,  and  under  no  circumstances  to  employ 
a  printer  living  beyond  its  boundary.  Now  the  astute  agent, 
eager  to  conciliate  the  whole  body  of  organised  workmen  in 
the  constituency,  confines  his  printing  strictly  to  the  best 
Trade  Union  establishments,  although  this  usually  involves 
passing  over  most  of  the  local  establishments  and  sometimes 
even  giving  work  to  firms  outside  the  district.  The  influence 
of  the  Trade  Union  leaders  is  used,  not  to  maintain  their 
respective  trades  in  all  the  places  in  which  they  happen  to 
exist,  but  to  strengthen,  at  the  expense  of  the  rest,  those 
establishments,  those  towns,  and  even  those  districts,  in  which 
the  conditions  of  work  are  most  advantageous. 

We  see,  therefore,  that  in  spite  of  the  difficulties  of 
government,  in  spite  of  the  strong  inherited  tradition  of 
local  exclusiveness,  and  in  spite,  too,  of  the  natural  selfish- 
ness of  each  branch  in  desiring  to  preserve  its  own  local 
monopoly,  the  unit  of  government  in  the  workmen's  organ- 
isations, in  complete  contrast  to  the  gilds  of  the  master- 

i  Special  meeting  of  General  Council  of  Amalgamated  Association  of  Cotton 
Weavers,  soth  April  1892,  attended  by  one  of  the  authors  j  see  other  instances 
cited  in  the  chapter  on  "The  Standard  Rate.n 


The  Unit  of  Government  8 1 

craftsmen,  has  become  the  trade  instead  of  the  town.1 
Our  description  of  this  irresistible  tendency  to  expan- 
sion has  already  to  some  extent  revealed  its  cause,  in  the 
Trade  Union  desire  to  secure  uniform  minimum  conditions 
throughout  each  industry.  In  our  examination  of  the 
Methods  and  Regulations  of  Trade  Unionism,  and  in  our 
analysis  of  their  economic  working,  we  shall  discover  the 
means  by  which  the  wage-earners  seek  to  attain  this  end, 
and  the  reasons  which  convince  them  of  its  importance. 
In  the  final  part  of  our  work  we  shall  examine  how  far  such 
an  equality  is  economically  possible  or  desirable.  For  the 
moment  the  reader  must  accept  the  fact  that  this  uniformity 
of  minimum  is,  whether  wisely  or  not,  the  most  permanent 
of  Trade  Union  aspirations. 

Meanwhile  it  is  interesting  to  note  that  this  conception 
of  the  solidarity  of  each  trade  as  a  whole  is  checked  by 
racial  differences.  The  great  national  unions  of  Engineers 
ind  Carpenters  find  no  difficulty  in  extending  their  organisa- 
tions beyond  national  boundaries,  and  easily  open  branches 
in  the  United  States  or  the  South  African  Republic,  France 
or  Spain,  provided  that  these  branches  are  composed  of  British 
workmen.2  But  it  is  needless  to  say  that  it  has  not  yet 
ippeared  practicable  to  any  British  Trade  Union  even  to 
suggest  amalgamation  with  the  Trade  Union  of  any  other 
mntry.  Differences  in  legal  position,  in  political  status,  in 
industrial  methods,  and  in  the  economic  situation  between 

1  Where  at  the  present  day  a  widespread  English  industry  is  without  a  pre- 
Dnderating  national  Trade  Union,  it  is  simply  a  mark  of  imperfect  organisation. 

ms  the  numerous  little  Trade  Unions  of  Painters,  and  Chippers  and  Drillers 
:lude  only  a  small  proportion  of  those  at  work  in  the  trades. 

2  The  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  had,  in  1896,  82  branches  beyond 
ic  United  Kingdom,  and  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Carpenters  and  Joiners  no 

fewer  than  87.  About  half  of  these  are  in  the  United  States  or  Canada,  and 
most  of  the  remainder  in  the  Australian  Colonies  or  South  Africa.  The  Engineers 
had  one  branch  in  France,  at  Croix,  and  formerly  one  in  Spain,  at  Bilbao, 
where  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers  also  had  a  branch  until  1894.  In  the 
years  1880-82  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers  even  had  a  branch  at  Con- 
stantinople. The  only  other  English  Trade  Union  having  branches  beyond  sea 
is  the  Steam-Engine  Makers'  Society,  which  has  opened  lodges  at  New  York, 
Montreal,  and  Brisbane. 

VOL.  I  G 


82  Trade  Union  Structure 

French  and  English  workers — not  to  mention  the  barrier  of 
language — easily  account  for  the  indisposition  on  the  part 
of  practical  British  workmen  to  consider  an  international 
amalgamated  union.  And  it  is  significant  that,  even  within 
the  British  Isles,  the  progress  towards  national  union  has 
been  much  hampered  by  differences  of  racial  sentiment  and 
divergent  views  of  social  expediency.  The  English  carpenter, 
plumber,  or  smith  who  finds  himself  working  in  a  Scotch 
town,  is  apt  to  declare  the  Scotch  union  in  his  trade  to  be 
little  better  than  a  friendly  society,  and  to  complain  that 
Scotch  workmen  are  too  eager  for  immediate  gain  and  for 
personal  advancement  sufficiently  to  resist  such  dangerous 
innovations  as  competitive  piecework,  nibbling  at  the 
Standard  Rate,  or  habitual  overtime.  The  Scotchman 
retorts  that  the  English  Trade  Union  is  extravagant  in  its 
expenditure,  especially  at  the  head  office  in  London  or 
Manchester,  and  unduly  restrictive  in  its  Regulations  and 
Methods.  In  some  cases  the  impulse  towards  amalgama- 
tion has  prevailed  over  this  divergence  as  to  what  is  socially 
expedient.  The  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  which 
extends  without  a  rival  from  sea  to  sea,  was  able  in  1889, 
through  the  loyalty  of  the  bulk  of  its  Scottish  members,  to 
stamp  out  an  attempted  secession,  aiming  at  a  national 
society  on  the  banks  of  the  Clyde,  which  evoked  the  support 
of  Scottish  national  feeling,  voiced  by  the  Glasgow  Trades 
Council.  In  other  cases  Scotch  pertinacity  has  conquered 
England.  The  Associated  Shipwrights'  Society,  the  rise  and 
national  development  of  which  we  have  already  described, 
sprang  out  of  the  Glasgow  Shipwrights'  Union,  which  gave 
to  the  wider  organisation  its  able  and  energetic  secretary, 
Mr.  Alexander  Wilkie.  The  British  Steel  Smelters'  Associa- 
tion (established  1886)  has  spread  from  Glasgow  over  the 
whole  industry  in  the  Northern  and  Midland  districts  of 
England.  In  both  these  cases  the  Scotch  have  "  stooped 
to  conquer,"  the  Scottish  secretary  moving  to  an  English 
town  as  the  centre  of  membership  shifted  towards  the  south. 
But  in  other  trades  the  prevailing  tendency  towards  complete 


The  Unit  of  Government  83 

national  amalgamation  is  still  baffled  by  the  sturdy  Scotch 
determination — due  partly  to  differences  of  administration 
but  mainly  to  racial  sentiment — not  to  be  "  governed  from 
England."  l  The  powerful  English  national  unions  of  Car- 
penters, Handworking  Bootmakers,  Plumbers,  and  Bricklayers 
have  either  never  attempted  or  have  failed  to  persuade  their 
Scottish  fellow-workmen  to  give  up  their  separate  Scottish 
societies.  The  rival  national  societies  of  Tailors  are  always 
at  war,  making  periodical  excursions  across  the  Border,  this 
establishment  of  branches  in  each  other's  territories  giving 
rise  to  heated  recriminations.  In  many  important  trades, 
such  as  the  Compositors,  Stonemasons,  and  Ironfounders, 
effective  Trade  Unionism  is  as  old  in  Scotland  as  in 
England,  and  the  two  national  societies  in  each  trade,  whilst 
retaining  complete  Home  Rule,  have  settled  down  to  a 
fraternal  relationship,  which  amounts  to  tacit  if  not  formal 
federation. 

Ireland  presents  a  similar  case  of  racial  differences, 
working  in  a  somewhat  different  manner.  Whereas  the 
English  Trade  Unions  have  keenly  desired  union  with 
Scottish  local  societies,  they  have,  until  lately,  manifested  a 
marked  dislike  to  having  anything  to  do  with  Ireland.2  This 
has  been,  in  some  cases  at  least,  the  result  of  experience. 

1  Analogous  tendencies  may  be  traced  in   the  Friendly  Society  movement, 
though  to  a  lesser  extent.      The  Scottish  lodges  of  the  Manchester  Unity  of  Odd- 
fellows have  their  own  peculiar  rules.      The  Scottish  delegates  to  the  Foresters' 
High  Court  at  Edinburgh  in  1894,  were  among  the  most  strenuous  opponents 
of  the  proposal  to  fix  the  headquarters  (at  present  moving  annually  from  town  to 
town)  in  London  or  Birmingham.     And  though  exclusively  Scottish  Orders  have 
never  yet  succeeded  in  widely  establishing  themselves,  it  is  not  uncommon  for 
Scottish  lodges  to  threaten  secession,  as  when,  in  1889,  five  Scottish  lodges  of 
the  Bolton  Unity  of  the  Ancient  Noble  Order  of  Oddfellows  endeavoured  to  start 
a  new  "Scottish  Unity"  (Oddfellows'  Magazine,  March  1889,  p.  70).     Such  a 
secession  from  the  Manchester  Unity  resulted  in  the  "  Scottish  Order  of  Odd- 
fellows" which  has,  however,  under  2000  members.      There  exist  also  the  "St. 
Andrew's  Order  of  Ancient  Free  Gardeners  of  Scotland,"  with  6000  members,  and 
a  "  United  Order  of  Scottish  Mechanics,"  with  4000  members,  which  refuse  to 
merge  themselves  in  the  larger  Orders. 

2  Scottish  branches  are  declared  by  Trade  Union  secretaries  to  be  profitable 
recruits  from  a  financial  point  of  view,  because  they  are  habitually  frugal  and 
cautious  in  dispensing  friendly  benefits. 


84  Trade  Union  Structure 

From  1832  down  to  1840,  Irish  lodges  were  admitted  to 
the  Friendly  Society  of  Operative  Stonemasons,  on  the  same 
footing  as  English,  whilst  the  Scotch  masons  had  already 
their  independent  organisation.  The  fortnightly  reports 
during  these  years  reveal  constant  friction  between  the 
central  executive  and  the  Irish  branches,  who  would  not 
agree  among  themselves,  and  who  persisted  in  striking 
against  members  from  other  Irish  towns.  At  the  Delegate 
Meeting  in  1839  the  Irish  branches  had  to  be  specially 
deprived  of  the  right  to  strike  without  prior  permission,  even 
in  those  cases  in  which  the  rules  allowed  to  English  branches 
the  instantaneous  cessation  of  work  to  resist  encroachments 
on  established  customs.1  But  even  with  this  precaution 
the  drain  of  the  Irish  lodges  upon  the  English  members 
became  unendurable.  At  length  in  1840,  the  general 
secretary  was  sent  on  a  special  mission  of  investigation, 
which  revealed  every  kind  of  financial  irregularity.  The 
Irish  lodges  were  found  to  have  an  incurable  propensity  to 
dispense  benefits  to  all  and  sundry  irrespective  of  the  rules, 
and  an  invincible  objection  to  English  methods  of  account- 
keeping.  The  Dublin  lodge  had  to  be  dissolved  as  a 
punishment  for  retaining  to  itself  monies  remitted  by  the 
Central  Committee  for  other  Irish  lodges.  The  central 
executive  who,  in  1837,  had  successfully  resisted  a  proposi- 
tion emanating  from  a  Warwickshire  district  in  favor  of 
Home  Rule  for  Ireland,  "  as  such  separation  would  injure 
the  stability  of  the  society,"  2  now  reported  in  its  favor.  "  We 
are  convinced,"  says  the  report,  "  that  a  very  great  amount 
of  money  had  been  sent  to  Ireland  for  the  relief  of  tramps, 
etc.  ...  to  which  they  had  no  legal  right.  .  .  .  However 
much  a  separation  may  be  regretted,  we  feel  convinced  that 
until  they  are  thrown  more  on  their  own  resources,  they  will 
not  sufficiently  estimate  the  benefits  derivable  from  such  an 
institution  to  exert  themselves  on  its  behalf."  3  The  receipts 

1  Rules  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Operative  Stonemasons  (edition  of  1839). 

2  Resolutions  of  the  Delegate  Meeting  1837. 
3  Stonemason?  Fortnightly  Return,  2nd  January  1840. 


The  Unit  of  Government  85 

from  Ireland  for  the  year  had  been  £47  :  IDS.,  whilst  the 
remittances  to  Ireland  had  amounted  to  no  less  than  £545. 
It  is  not  surprising  that  the  society  promptly  voted  the 
exclusion  of  all  the  Irish  branches. 

In  1850  the  Executive  Committee  of  the  Provincial 
Typographical  Association  were  "reluctantly  compelled  to 
declare  their  conviction  that  no  English  executive  can 
successfully  manage  an  Association  embracing  branches  so 
geographically  distant  and  so  materially  different  in  their 
regulations  and  their  mode  of  remuneration  as  those  of  the 
sister  kingdom."  The  union  thereupon  gave  up  the  one 
Irish  branch  (Waterford)  which  had  not  already  insisted  on 
its  independence,  and  refused  to  entertain  any  proposals  for 
new  ones.1  Other  societies  which,  in  more  recent  years,  have 
had  Irish  branches  appear  to  have  found  them  equally  un- 
profitable, and  a  source  of  constant  trouble.  The  records  of 
the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Tailors  are  full  of  references  to 
the  extravagance  and  financial  mismanagement  of  its  Irish 
branches.  During  the  year  1892  no  less  than  four  of  the 
principal  Irish  branches  of  the  society  were  rebuked  by  the 
Executive  Council  upon  this  account.  One  of  these  had  sub- 
sequently to  be  closed,  the  Executive  stating  that  its  "  report 
is  altogether  wrong,  and  does  not  balance.  The  contributions 
do  not  average  lod.  per  member,  and  the  rent  of  the  club- 
room  is  more  than  the  whole  income  from  the  branch.  If  a 
satisfactory  explanation  is  not  sent  at  once  the  branch  must  be 
closed."2  Finally,  in  1896,  the  Executive  of  the  Associated 

1  Half -Yearly   Report   of  the   Provincial    Typographical  Association,    3ist 
December  1850. 

2  Quarterly  Report   of  the   Amalgamated  Society  of  Tailors,    April    1892. 
Report  on  the  Ennis  branch.      In  this  connection  the  following  extract  from  the 
proceedings  of  the  High  Court  of  the  Ancient  Order  of  Foresters  in  1894  will 
be  interesting.     The  executive  had  found  it  necessary  to  hold  a  special  investiga- 
tion into  the  affairs  of  the  Dublin  District ;  and  they  recommended  the  grant  of 
certain  advantages   upon   condition  of  reform.     This  proposal  led   to  a  lively 
debate.      "Were    they  going,"   said    one    prominent    Forester,    "to   encourage 
extravagant,   reckless,   and  fraudulent  mismanagement?     The  report  presented 
to    them   showed   distinctly   that   there   had   been   extravagant,    reckless,    and 
fraudulent  mismanagement.    .    .    .    Not   less   than    £997    had  been    voted    by 
previous  High  Courts  towards  the  relief  of  Dublin  Courts.   .   .  .  The  Order's 


86  Trade  Union  Structure 

Shipwrights'  Society  reported  that  it  had  been  compelled 
"  to  close  the  Dublin  branch,  notwithstanding  that  the  E.  C. 
had  instructed  both  the  general  secretary  and  the  Humber 
Delegate  to  visit  them.  We  have  not  been  able  to 
receive  any  correct  reports  from  them  for  some  time,  and 
the  only  word  we  could  get  from  them  was  that  there  was 
no  work  and  no  money,  yet  when  your  representatives 
visited  them  the  officers  were  so  busy  working  they  had  not 
time  to  convene  a  meeting  of  members.  .  .  .  Your  E.  C. 
offered  to  have  all  the  idle  men  sent  to  ports  where  em- 
ployment could  be  found  them,  but  we  are  informed  where 
this  has  been  done  some  of  these  men,  notwithstanding  all 
that  has  been  done  for  them,  refused  to  pay  up  their 
arrears,  and  rather  than  pay  left  their  employment  and  went 
home.  .  .  .  When  the  branch  books  were  examined  it  was 
found  they  were  paying  both  sick  and  unemployed  benefit 
to  members  who  were  not  entitled  to  it,  and  the  branch 
officers  were  receiving  salary  for  work  they  failed  or  refused 
to  do.  Seeing  the  Dublin  branch  entirely  ignored  the 
registered  rules,  your  E.  C.  had  no  other  option  but  to 
close  the  branch.  The  different  branches  must  deal  with 
these  men  should  they  come  to  their  ports."1 

So  strong,  however,  is  the  dominant  impulse  towards  the 
complete  union  of  a  trade  from  one  end  of  the  United 
Kingdom  to  the  other,  that  it  seems,  during  the  last  few 
years,  to  be  slowly  overcoming  the  reluctance  of  both  English 
and  Irish  organisations.  From  1889  onward,  we  find  such 
great  national  unions  as  the  Carpenters,  Railway  Servants, 
Engineers,  Tailors,  and  Shipwrights  freely  opening  branches 
in  Irish  towns  and  absorbing  the  surviving  trade  clubs  of 

Chief  Official  Valuer  said  'the  members  have  never  done  their  duty.'  That 
officer  thereupon  interposed  with  the  remark,  '  It  was  believed  that  in  connection 
with  sickness  there  was  a  good  deal  of  malingering.'  Another  prominent 
Forester  said  he  would  attach  the  (Dublin)  Courts  to  the  Glasgow  District.  .  .  . 
There  was  only  one  element  of  danger,  and  it  was  of  putting  too  many  Irishmen 
together."—  Foresters'  Miscellany  (September  1894),  p.  180. 

1   The  Fifty-eighth  Quarterly  Report,  July  to  September  1896,  of  the  Associ- 
ated Society  of  Shipwrights,  p.  8. 


The  Unit  of  Government  87 

local  artisans.1  The  Provincial  Typographical  Association, 
now  become  the  Typographical  Association,  has,  since  1878, 
opened  sixteen  branches  in  Ireland,  and  now  employs  a 
salaried  organiser  for  that  island,  whose  efforts  have  brought 
in  many  recruits.  This  tendency  has  been  greatly  assisted, 
especially  in  the  engineering  and  shipbuilding  trades,  by  the 
remarkable  industrial  development  of  Belfast.  Since  1860 
a  constant  stream  of  skilled  artisans  from  England  and 
Scotland  have  settled  in  that  town,  with  the  result  that  it 
now  possesses  strong  branches  of  all  the  national  unions  of 
both  countries.  With  the  shifting  of  the  effective  centre  of 
Irish  Trade  Unionism  from  Dublin  to  Belfast  has  come  an 
almost  irresistible  tendency  to  accept  an  English  or  Scottish 
government.  On  the  other  hand,  attempts  to  unite  the 
separate  local  societies  of  Irish  towns  in  national  Trade 
Unions  for  Ireland  have  almost  invariably  failed,  the  Irish 
clubs  displaying  far  more  willingness  to  become  branches  of 
British  unions  than  to  amalgamate  among  themselves.2 

Past  experience  of  British  Trade  Unionism  seems,  there- 
fore, to  point  to  the  whole  extent  of  each  trade  within  the 
British  Isles  as  forming  the  proper  unit  of  government  for 
any  combination  of  the  wage-earners  in  that  trade.  Any 
unit  of  smaller  area  produces  an  organisation  of  unstable 
equilibrium,  either  tending  constantly  to  expansion,  or  liable 
to  supersession  by  the  growth  of  a  rival  society.  But  there 
is  a  marked  contrast  between  the  union  of  Scotland  with 
England,  and  that  effected  between  either  of  them  and 
Ireland.  The  English  and  Scottish  Trade  Unions  federate 
or  combine  with  each  other  on  equal  terms.  If  complete 
amalgamation  is  decided  on,  it  is  frequently  the  Scotchman, 
bringing  with  him  Scotch  procedure  and  Scotch  traditions, 

1  The  Amalgamated  Society  of  Railway  Servants  now  (1897)  possesses  no 
fewer   than    56    Irish   branches,    the  Amalgamated   Society  of  Carpenters  and 
Joiners  56,  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Tailors  35,  the  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Engineers  19,  and  the  Associated  Shipwrights'  Society  9. 

2  Almost  the  only  Irish  national   trade  society  is  the  Operative  Bakers  of 
Ireland  National  Federal  Union,  formed  in  November  1889.     An  Irish  Trade 
Union  Congress  has  been  held  annually  since  1894. 


88  Trade  Union  Structure 

who  is  chosen  to  reign  in  England,  the  centre  of  government 
being  shifted  almost  automatically  to  the  main  centre  of  the 
industry.  Union  with  Ireland  invariably  means  the  simple 
absorption  of  the  Irish  branch,  and  the  unconditional  accept- 
ance of  the  English  or  Scottish  rules  and  organisation.  This 
is  usually  brought  about  by  the  English  or  Scottish  immi- 
grants into  Ireland,  aided  by  sections  of  Irish  members  who 
desire  to  escape  from  the  weakness  of  internal  dissensions, 
and  to  secure  the  benefits  of  efficient  administration,  with  the 
support  of  a  comparatively  wealthy  and  powerful  organisation.1 
Passing  now  from  the  boundaries  of  the  autonomous 
state  to  the  relation  between  central  and  local  authorities 
within  it,  we  watch  the  Trade  Unionists  breaking  away 
from  the  traditions  of  British  Democracy.  In  the  political 
expansion  of  the  Anglo-Saxon  race,  the  development  of 
local  institutions  has  at  least  kept  pace  with  the  extension 
of  empire.  In  the  other  great  organisations  of  the  British 
working  class,  which  have,  equally  with  Trade  Unionism, 
grown  from  small  local  beginnings  to  powerful  corporations 
of  national,  or  even  international  extent,  the  workmen  have 
successfully  maintained  the  complete  independence  of  each 
local  unit.  The  Co-operative  Movement  includes  within  the 
British  Isles  a  nominal  membership  as  great  as  that  of  Trade 
Unionism,  with  financial  transactions  many  times  larger  in 
amount.  The  1 700  separate  Co-operative  Societies  have 
united  in  the  colossal  business  federations  of  the  English 
and  Scottish  Wholesale  Societies,  and  in  the  educational 
and  political  federation  called  the  Co-operative  Union. 
But  though  the  Co-operative  Movement  has  gone  through 
many  developments  since  its  re-birth  in  1 844,  and  has  built 
up  a  u  State  within  the  State,"  the  great  federal  bodies  have 

1  It  may  not  be  improper  to  observe,  for  English  political  readers,  that 
the  authors  are  divided  in  opinion  as  to  the  policy  of  granting  Home  Rule  to 
Ireland,  and  are  therefore  protected  against  bias  in  drawing  political  inferences 
from  Trade  Union  experience  in  this  respect.  If  it  is  thought  that  the  facts 
adduced  in  this  chapter  tell  against  Irish  self-government,  the  considerations 
brought  forward  in  the  next  chapter  may  be  regarded  as  making  against  the 
policy  of  complete  union  with  Great  Britain. 


The  Unit  of  Government  89 

remained  in  all  cases  nothing  but  the  agents  and  servants  of 
the  local  societies.1  And  if  we  turn  to  a  movement  still 
more  closely  analogous  to  Trade  Unionism,  we  may  watch 
in  the  marvellous  expansion  of  the  "Affiliated  Orders" 
among  the  friendly  societies,  the  growth  of  a  world-wide 
working-class  organisation,  based  on  an  almost  complete 
autonomy  of  the  separate  "  lodges  "  within  each  "  Order."  2 
To  the  members  of  an  Oddfellows'  Court  or  a  Foresters' 
Lodge  any  proposal  to  submit  an  issue  of  policy  to  the 
federal  executive  would  seem  an  unheard-of  innovation.  But 
it  is  in  their  financial  system  that  this  insistence  on  com- 
plete local  autonomy  shows  itself  most  decisively.  How- 
ever strongly  the  qualities  of  benevolence  or  charity  may 
prevail  among  the  Foresters  or  the  Oddfellows,  it  has  never 
occurred  to  their  rich  Courts  or  Lodges  to  regard  their 
surplus  funds  as  being  freely  at  the  disposal  of  those  which 
were  unable  to  meet  their  engagements.  Each  retains  and 
controls  its  own  funds  for  its  own  purposes,  and  its  surplus 
balances  are  considered  as  being  as  much  the  private 
property  of  its  own  particular  members  as  their  individual 
investments. 

To  outward  seeming  the  scattered  members  of  a  national 
Trade  Union  enjoy  no  less  local  self-government  than  those 
of  the  Ancient  Order  of  Foresters  or  the  Manchester 
Unity  of  Oddfellows.  If  the  reader  were  to  seek  out,  in  some 
tavern  of  an  industrial  centre,  the  local  meeting-place  of  the 
Foresters  or  the  Carpenters,  the  Oddfellows  or  the  Boiler- 
makers, he  might  easily  fail,  on  a  first  visit,  to  detect  any 
important  difference  between  the  Trade  Union  branch  and 
the  court  or  lodge  of  the  friendly  society.  The  Oddfellows 
who  use  the  club-room  on  a  Monday,  the  Carpenters  who 
meet  there  on  a  Tuesday,  the  Foresters  who  assemble  on  a 
Thursday,  and  the  Stonemasons  or  Boilermakers  who  come 

1  The  Co-operative  Movement  in  Great  Britain,  by  Beatrice  Potter  (Mrs. 
Sidney  Webb). 

2  See  The  Friendly  Societies'  Movement  (London,  1885)  and  Mutual  Thrift 
(London,  1892),  by  the  Rev.  J.  Frome  Wilkinson,   and  English  Associations  of 
Working  Men,  by  Dr.  J.  Baernreither  (London,  1892). 


9<D  Trade  Union  Structure 

on  successive  Fridays,  all  seem  "  clubs  "  managing  their  own 
affairs.  Every  night  sees  the  same  interminable  proces- 
sion of  men,  women,  and  children  bringing  the  contribution 
money.  When  the  deliberations  begin,  they  all  affect  the 
same  traditional  mystery  about  "keeping  the  door,"  and 
retain  the  long  pause  outside  before  admitting  the  nervous 
aspirant  for  "  initiation  "  ;  they  all  "  open  the  lodge  "  with  the 
same  kind  of  cautious  solemnity,  and  dignify  with  strange 
titles  and  formal  methods  of  address  the  officers  whom  they 
are  perpetually  electing  and  re-electing.  But  if  the  visitor 
listens  carefully  he  will  notice,  in  the  Trade  Union  business, 
constant  references  to  mysterious  outside  authorities.  The 
whole  branch  may  show  itself  in  favor  of  the  grant  of 
benefit  to  a  particular  applicant,  but  the  secretary  will 
observe  that  any  such  payment  would  have  to  come  out 
of  his  own  pocket,  as  the  central  executive  has  intimated 
that  the  case  is  not  within  its  interpretation  of  the  rules. 
The  branch  treasurer  may  announce  that  the  balance  in 
hand  has  suddenly  sunk  to  a  few  pounds,  as  he  has  been 
ordered  by  the  central  office  to  remit  £100  to  a  branch  at 
the  other  end  of  the  kingdom.  And  when  a  question  arises 
as  to  some  dispute  with  an  employer,  the  visitor  will  be 
surprised  to  find  that  this  characteristic  Trade  Union  business 
is  not  in  the  hands  of  the  branch  at  all,  but  is  being  tlealt 
with  by  another  outside  authority,  the  "  district,"  on  instruc- 
tions from  the  general  secretary. 1 

Trade  Unionism  has,  in  fact,  been  based  from  the  outset 
on  the  principle  of  the  solidarity  of  the  trade.  Even  the 
eighteenth-century  clubs  of  handicraftsmen,  without  national 
organisation  of  any  kind,  habitually  contributed  their  surplus 

1  Branch  meetings  of  Trade  Unions  are  private,  but  it  is  not  impossible  for  a 
bona-fide  student  of  Trade  Unionism  to  gain  admission  as  the  friend  of  one  of  the 
officials.  The  authors  have  attended  branch  meetings  of  almost  every  trade  in 
various  industrial  centres,  and  have  found  their  proceedings  of  great  interest,  not 
only  as  revealing  the  inner  working  of  Trade  Unionism,  but  also  as  displaying 
the  marked  differences  of  physique,  intellect,  and  character  between  the  different 
sections  of  the  wage-earning  class,  often  erroneously  regarded  as  homogeneous. 
Some  of  these  differences  are  referred  to  in  the  chapter  on  "  The  Assumptions  of 
Trade  Unionism." 


The  Unit  of  Government  g  i 

balances  in  support  of  each  other's  temporary  needs.  When 
the  clubs  drew  together  in  a  national  union,  it  was 
assumed,  as  a  matter  of  course,  that  any  cash  in  pos- 
session of  any  branch  was  available  for  the  needs  of  any 
other  branch.  Thus  we  learn  from  the  resolution  of  the 
Stonemasons'  Delegate  Meeting  of  1833,  that  the  several 
lodges  were  expected  spontaneously  to  send  their  surplus 
monies  to  the  aid  of  any  district  engaged  in  a  strike.1  This 
archaic  trustfulness  in  the  brotherhood  of  man  still  contents 
such  a  conservative -minded  trade  as  the  Coopers,  whose 
"  Mutual  Association  "  remains  only  a  loose  alliance  of  local 
clubs,  aiding  each  other's  disputes  by  voluntary  grants.2  But 
in  the  large  industries  the  same  spirit  soon  embodied  itself 
in  formal  machinery.  Among  the  Stonemasons  the  primi- 
tive arrangement  was,  it  is  not  surprising  to  learn,  in  the 
opinion  of  the  "  Grand  Central  Committee,"  "  wholly  in- 
efficient," each  district  sending  only  such  funds  as  it  chose, 
and  selecting  which  out  of  several  districts  on  strike  it  would 
support.  The  next  step,  which  appears  in  the  first  manu- 
script rules  (probably  of  1834),  was  to  make  each  branch 
"  immediately  contribute  a  proportionate  share  "  of  the  cost 
of  maintaining  each  strike,  fixed  by  the  Grand  Committee. 
Finally,  in  1837,  we  have  what  has  become  the  typical  Trade 
Union  arrangement  of  a  fund  belonging,  not  to  the  branch, 
but  to  the  society  ;  available  only  for  the  purposes  prescribed 
by  the  rules,  but  within  those  purposes  common  to  the  whole 
organisation. 

It  is  easy  to  understand  why  the  Stonemasons,  dispersed 
over  the  country  in  relatively  small  groups,  each  conscious 
of  its  own  isolation  and  weakness  in  face  of  the  great 
capitalist  contractor,  should  quickly  seize  the  idea  of  a 
common  "  war-chest."  The  Carpenters,  working  under  much 

1  Circular   of    "Grand    Central    Committee,"    held    in    Manchester,    28th 
November  1833,  preserved  in  the  records  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Operative 
Stonemasons. 

2  See  the  various  "  monthly  reports"  of  the  Mutual  Association  of  Coopers. 
A  proposal  is  under  discussion  to  form  a  central  fund,  fed  by  regular  contributions 
for  the  aid  of  any  branch  under  attack. 


0,2  Trade  Union  Structure 

the  same  circumstances,  express  this  feeling  in  the  following 
terms  :  "  Although  oceans  may  separate  us  from  each  other, 
our  interests  are  identical ;  and  if  we  become  united  under 
one  constitution,  governed  by  one  code  of  rules,  having  one 
common  fund  available  wherever  it  may  be  required,  we  thus 
acquire  a  power  which,  if  judiciously  exercised,  will  protect 
our  interests  more  effectually  and  will  confer  greater  advan- 
tages than  can  possibly  be  derived  from  any  partial  union."  1 
But  we  may  see  the  same  process  of  financial  centralisation 
at  work  in  trades  densely  concentrated  in  a  small  area.  The 
Cotton-spinners  of  Oldham  and  the  surrounding  towns  were, 
down  to  1879,  organised  as  a  federation  of  ten  financially 
autonomous  societies,  each  collecting,  expending,  and  invest- 
ing its  own  funds.  The  great  trade  struggle  of  1877-78 
revealed  the  weakness  of  this  form  of  organisation.  To 
quote  the  words  of  an  official  of  the  trade,2  "  The  result 
was  that  when  a  strike  occurred,  some  of  the  branches  were 
on  the  point  of  bankruptcy,  whilst  others  were  in  a  good 
position  as  regards  funds  for  maintaining  the  struggle.  They 
soon  found  out  their  real  fighting  strength  was  gauged,  not 
by  the  worth  of  their  richest  branch,  but  by  the  poorest.  It 
was  another  exemplification  of  the  old  law  of  mechanics  that 
the  strength  of  the  chain  is  represented  by  its  weakest  link. 
After  the  struggle  they  remedied  the  defect  by  enacting  that 
all  surplus  funds  should  be  deposited  in  one  common 
account."  Since  that  time  each  division  of  the  Lancashire 
Cotton-spinners  has  adopted  the  principle  of  centralised  funds. 
"We  hold,"  says  the  General  Secretary  of  the  Bolton 
SpinnerSj  "  that  where  the  labour  of  any  number  of  men  is 
subject  to  the  same  fluctuations  of  trade,  when  the  product 
of  their  labour  goes  into  the  same  market,  and  when  the 
prices  and  conditions  which  regulate  their  wages  are  identical, 
it  is  imperative  upon  such  men,  if  they  wish  to  protect  their 

1  Preface  to  the  Rules  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Carpenters  and  Joiners 
(Manchester,  1891). 

^  2  The  late  John  Fielding,  secretary  of  the  Bolton  Provincial  Operative  Cotton- 
spinners'  Association,  one  of  the  ablest  leaders  of  the  Cotton-spinners. 


The  Unit  of  Government  93 

labour,  to  combine  together  in  one  association.  It  is  not 
sufficient  that  they  shall  join  separate  district  societies  which 
in  time  may  boast  of  possessing  a  respectable  reserve  fund 
entirely  under  their  own  control.  We  have  no  hesitation  in 
saying  that  any  such  accumulated  funds  are  of  little  use  in 
promoting  their  purely  trade  interests."  l 

The  paramount  necessity  of  a  central  fund,  available  for 
the  defence  of  any  branch  that  might  be  involved  in  indus- 
trial war,  has  become  so  plain  to  every  Trade  Unionist  that 
society  after  society  has  adopted  the  principle  of  a  common 
purse.  But  a  common  purse,  as  one  or  two  striking  instances 
among  successful  friendly  societies  prove,  does  not,  in  itself, 
necessarily  involve  the  establishment  of  a  dominant  central 
executive  wielding  all  administrative  power.  Where  business 
can  be  reduced  to  precise  rules,  into  the  carrying  out  of 
which  no  question  of  policy  enters,  and  no  discretion  is 
allowed,  experience  shows,  as  we  shall  presently  see,  that 
local  branch  administration  may  be  as  efficient  and  econo- 
mical as  that  of  a  central  authority.  But  the  expenditure 
of  the  Trade  Union  funds  is  determined,  not  exclusively  by 
the  legislation  of  its  members,  but  largely  by  the  judgment 
of  its  administrators.  In  all  matters  of  trade  protection, 
whether  it  be  the  elaboration  of  a  complicated  list  of  piece- 
work prices,  the  promotion  of  a  new  factory  bill,  the  nego- 
tiation of  a  national  agreement  with  the  associated  employers, 
or  the  conduct  of  a  strike,  it  passes  the  wit  of  man  to  pre- 
scribe by  any  written  rule  the  exact  method  or  amount  of 
the  expenditure  to  be  incurred.  It  follows  that  the  larger 
and  most  distinctive  part  of  Trade  Union  administration, 
unlike  the  award  of  friendly  benefits,  cannot  be  predeter- 
mined by  any  law  or  scale,  but  must  be  left  to  the  discretion 
of  the  executive  authority.  To  vest  this  discretion  abso- 
lutely and  exclusively  in  the  central  executive  representing 
the  whole  body  of  members  is,  it  is  plain,  the  only  way  by 
which  those  who  have  contributed  the  income  can  retain 

1  Annual  Report  of  the  Bolton  Provincial  Operative  Cotton-stinners'  Associa- 
tion, 1882. 


94  Trade  Union  Structure 

any  control  over  its  expenditure.  But  this  development 
necessarily  entails  the  withdrawal  from  the  branches  of  all 
real  autonomy  in  issues  of  policy  and  in  the  expenditure  of 
their  part  of  the  common  income.  It  follows  necessarily  from 
the  merging  of  the  branch  monies  into  a  fund  common  to 
the  whole  society,  and  from  the  replenishment  of  this  fund 
by  levies  upon  all  the  members  alike,  that  no  local  branch 
can  safely  be  permitted  to  involve  the  whole  organisation  in 
war.  Centralisation  of  finance  implies,  in  a  militant  organi- 
sation, centralisation  of  administration.  Those  Trade  Unions 
which  have  most  completely  recognised  this  fact  have  proved 
most  efficient,  and  therefore  most  stable.  Where  funds  have 
been  centralised,  and  power  nevertheless  left,  through  the 
inadvertence  or  lack  of  skill  of  the  framers  of  the  rules,  to 
local  authorities,  the  result  has  been  weakness,  divided 
counsels,  and  financial  disaster. 

This  cardinal  principle  of  democratic  finance  has  been 
only  slowly  and  imperfectly  learnt  by  Trade  Unionists,  and 
a  lack  of  clear  insight  into  the  matter  still  produces  calami- 
tous results  in  large  and  powerful  organisations.  To  take, 
for  instance,  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers,  which 
was  formed  for  the  express  purpose  of  bringing  about  a 
uniform  trade  policy  under  the  control  of  a  central  executive. 
It  was  intended  to  secure  this  result  by  providing  that  strike 
pay  should  be  awarded  only  by  the  central  executive,  leaving 
the  branches  to  dispense  the  other  benefits  prescribed  by 
the  rules.  But  unfortunately  this  strike  pay  amounts  only  to 
five  shillings  a  week,  it  being  assumed  that  the  member  leav- 
ing his  work  will  also  be  receiving  the  Out  of  Work  donation 
of  ten  shillings  a  week,  awarded  by  his  branch.  This  con- 
fusion of  trade  with  friendly  benefits  has  resulted  in  a  serious 
weakening  of  the  authority  of  the  central  executive  in  matters 
of  trade  policy.  Whenever  the  men  working  in  any  engineer- 
ing establishment  are  dissatisfied  with  any  decision  of  their 
employer,  they  can  appeal  to  their  own  branch,  and,  on 
obtaining  its  permission,  may  drop  their  tools,  with  the 
certainty  that  they  will  receive  at  the  cost  of  the  whole 


The  Unit  of  Government  95 

society  the  Out  of  Work  benefit  of  ten  shillings  a  week.1 
The  matter  will  be  reported,  in  due  course,  by  the  district 
committee  to  the  central  executive,  even  if  the  branch  itself 
does  not  trouble  to  apply  for  permission  to  pay  the  additional 
five  shillings  a  week  contingent  benefit.  But  meanwhile, 
war  has  been  declared,  and  has  actually  begun  ;  the  local 
employers  may  have  retaliated  with  a  lock-out,  the  whole 
district  may  even  have  "  come  out "  in  support  of  their 
fellow-workmen  ;  and  the  society  may  find  its  prestige  and 
honor  involved  in  maintaining  a  great  industrial  conflict 
without  its  central  executive  ever  having  decided  that  the 
point  at  issue  was  one  which  should  be  fought  at  all.  This, 
indeed,  is  precisely  what  happened  in  the  most  disastrous 
and  discreditable  of  recent  trade  disputes,  the  prolonged 
strike  of  the  Engineers  and  Plumbers  in  the  Tyneside  ship- 
building yards  in  1892,  when  thousands  of  men  were  idle 
for  over  three  months,  not  in  order  to  raise  the  Standard  ot 
Life  of  themselves  or  any  other  section  of  the  workers,  but 
because  the  local  Engineers  and  Plumbers  could  not  agree 
as  to  which  of  them  should  fit  up  two -and -a -half  inch 
iron  piping.  It  would  be  easy  for  any  student  of  the 
records  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  to  pick 
out  many  other  cases  in  which  branches  have,  by  paying 
the  Out  of  Work  donation  to  members  refusing  work, 
initiated  important  trade  movements  on  their  own  account, 
without  the  prior  knowledge  or  consent  of  the  central 
executive. 

This  unfortunate  confusion  between  Out  of  Work 
benefit  and  strike  pay  is  not  the  only  ambiguity  that 
perplexes  the  administrators  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Engineers.  Although  any  authorised  dispute  is  supported 

1  This  injurious  practice  has  been  greatly  strengthened  by  the  fact  that  the 
"contingent  fund,"  out  of  which  alone  the  strike  pay  could  formerly  be  granted, 
has  often  been  abolished  and  subsequently  re-established,  by  votes  of  the 
members.  During  the  periods  in  which  the  contingent  fund  did  not  exist,  the 
society  had  no  other  means  of  resisting  encroachments  than  the  award  of  Out  of 
Work  benefit  to  members  who  refused  to  submit  to  them.  But  this  left  the 
decision  to  the  branch,  though  the  funds  which  it  dispensed  were  levied  equally 
on  the  whole  society. 


9  6  Trade  Union  Structure 

from  the  funds  of  the  society  as  a  whole,  it  is  left  to  the 
local  members  through  their  district  committee  to  begin  the 
quarrel.  This  would  seem  to  mean  complete  local  autonomy, 
and  it  is  cherished  as  such  by  the  more  active  branches. 
But  the  rule  also  provides  that  the  resolutions  of  district 
committees  shall  be  "  subject  to  the  approval "  of  the  central 
executive,  the  ultimate  veto,  though  not  the  direction  of  the 
policy,  being  thus  vested  in  headquarters.  The  incapacity  of 
the  Engineers  to  make  up  their  minds  whether  or  not  they 
desire  local  autonomy  in  trade  policy,  has  more  than  once 
placed  the  society  in  an  invidious  and  even  ludicrous  position. 
Thus,  in  the  autumn  of  1895  the  Belfast  branches,  with  the 
confirmation  of  the  central  executive,  struck  for  an  advance. 
The  federated  employers  thereupon  locked  out,  not  only  all 
the  Belfast  engineers,  but  also  those  on  the  Clyde.  In  the 
negotiations  which  ensued  the  central  executive  naturally 
represented  the  society,  and  eventually  arranged  a  com- 
promise, which  was  approved  by  the  Clyde  branches.  The 
Belfast  branches,  on  the  other  hand,  refused  to  accept  the 
agreement  or  to  consider  the  strike  at  an  end,  and  went  on 
issuing  full  strike  pay,  from  the  funds  of  the  whole  society, 
to  all  their  members.  The  central  executive  found  itself 
bitterly  reproached  by  the  federated  employers  for  what 
seemed  a  breach  of  faith,  and  public  opinion  was  scandalised 
by  the  lack  of  loyalty  and  discipline.  Eventually  the  dead- 
lock was  ended  by  the  central  executive  taking  upon  itself 
peremptorily  to  order  the  Belfast  members  to  resume  work, 
without  waiting  for  the  resolution  of  the  district  committee. 
Whether  the  central  executive  had  any  right  to  intervene  at 
all,  otherwise  than  by  confirming  or  disallowing  a  resolution 
of  the  district  committee,  became  a  matter  of  heated  con- 
troversy; and  the  Delegate  Meeting  of  1896  not  only  passed 
a  resolution  censuring  this  action,  but  also  framed  a  new 
rule  which  expressly  deprives  both  the  central  executive  and 
the  district  committee  of  the  power  of  closing  a  dispute,  by 
making  the  consent  of  a  two-thirds  majority  of  the  local 
members — some  or  all  of  whom  must  be  the  very  persons 


The  Unit  of  Government  9  7 

concerned — necessary  to  the  closing  of  a  strike.1  This 
fanatical  attachment  of  the  Engineers  to  an  extreme  local 
autonomy — their  persistent  assumption  that  any  one  section, 
however  small  and  unimportant,  ought  to  be  allowed  to  draw 
on  the  funds  of  the  whole  society  in  support  of  a  policy  of 
which  the  majority  of  the  members  may  disapprove — has 
done  incalculable  harm  to  the  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Engineers.  It  has  been  the  source  of  a  continuous  and  need- 
less drain  on  the  society's  resources.  It  has  more  than  once 
involved  thousands  of  members  in  a  lock-out,  when  they  had 
no  quarrel  of  their  own.  It  deprives  the  federated  employers 
of  all  confidence  in  those  who  meet  them  on  the  workmen's 
behalf.  And,  most  important  of  all,  it  effectually  prevents 
the  society  from  maintaining  any  genuine  defence  of  the 
conditions  of  its  members'  employment.  National  agree- 
ments such  as  are  concluded  by  the  United  Society  of  Boiler- 
makers, the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton- 
spinners,  and  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe 
Operatives,  by  which  a  general  levelling-up  of  conditions  is 
secured,  must  necessarily  be  out  of  the  power  of  an  organ- 
isation which  cannot  give  its  negotiators  the  mandate  of  a 
common  will. 

The  same  conflict  between  centralisation  of  finance  and 
the  surviving  local  autonomy  of  the  branches  may  be  traced 
in  the  rules  of  most  of  the  unions  in  the  building  trade. 
Here  the  tradition  has  been  to  require  the  assent  of  the 
whole  society,  or  of  the  central  executive  as  its  representa- 
tive, before  any  branch  may  strike,  or  even  negotiate,  for  an 
increase  of  wages  or  new  trade  privileges.  But  it  has  been 
no  less  firmly  rooted  in  the  practice  of  the  building  trades, 
for  any  branch,  or  even  any  individual  workman,  instantly 
to  cease  work,  without  consulting  the  central  executive, 
whenever  an  employer  makes  an  encroachment  on  the 
existing  Working  Rules  of  that  town.  In  such  cases,  by 
the  rules  of  most  of  the  national  unions  in  these  trades, 
strike  pay  is  granted  by  the  branch  as  a  matter  of  course. 

1  Rules  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  (London,  1896),  p.  54. 
VOL.  I  H 


98  Trade  Union  Structure 

A  branch  is  accordingly  expressly  authorised  to  involve  the 
whole  society  in  war,  whenever  its  own  interpretation  of 
existing  customs  is  challenged  by  an  employer,  even  in  the 
minutest  particular.  We  may  easily  imagine  how  greatly 
international  hostilities  would  be  increased,  if  the  governor 
of  every  colony  or  out-lying  dependency  were  authorised 
instantly  to  declare  war,  in  the  name  and  on  the  resources 
of  the  whole  empire,  whenever,  in  his  own  private  judg- 
ment, any  infringement  of  national  rights  had  taken  place. 
And  although,  in  the  Trade  Union  instance,  each  particular 
branch  dispute  is  usually  neither  momentous  nor  prolonged, 
the  result  is  a  captious  and  spasmodic  trade  policy,  some- 
times even  ridiculous  in  its  inconsistency,  which  the  central 
executive  has  no  effective  power  to  check.  The  Friendly 
Society  of  Operative  Stonemasons  and  the  Operative  Brick- 
layers' Society  have,  until  recent  years,  specially  suffered  from 
a  constant  succession  of  petty  quarrels  with  particular  em- 
ployers, most  of  which  would  have  been  avoided  if  the  point 
at  issue  had  been  made  the  subject  of  quiet  negotiation  by 
an  officer  acting  on  behalf  of  the  whole  society.1  This  has 
been  dimly  perceived  by  the  leaders  of  the  building  trades. 
Among  the  Bricklayers  and  Stonemasons,  the  traditional 
right  of  the  branch  to  strike  against  encroachments,  without 
authorisation  from  the  central  executive,  has  hitherto  been 
too  firmly  held  to  be  abolished  ;  but  the  newer  editions 
of  the  rules  expressly  limit  this  right  to  certain  kinds 
_of  encroachment,  and  require  the  branch  to  obtain  the 

1  Sometimes  the  interpretation  placed  by  two  branches  on  the  Working  Rules 
of  one  or  both  of  them  may  seriously  differ.  The  Kendal  branch  of  the 
Friendly  Society  of  Operative  Stonemasons  had,  in  1873,  m  ^ts  Working  Rules, 
a  provision  requiring  employers  to  provide  dinner  for  men  sent  to  work  beyond 
a  certain  distance  from  their  homes  in  the  town.  A  Kendal  employer  sent 
members  of  the  Kendal  branch  to  a  place  twenty  miles  away  which  was 
within  the  district  of  another  branch  having  no  such  rule.  The  Kendal  masons 
insisted  on  their  employer  complying  with  the  Kendal  rules,  whereupon  he 
replaced  them  by  men  belonging  to  the  local  branch,  who  contended  that  the 
Kendal  rules  did  not  apply  to  work  done  in  their  district.  This  fine  point  in 
interpretation  led  to  endless  recrimination  between  the  two  branches,  and  much 
local  friction.  Finally  the  issue  was  referred  to  a  vote  of  the  whole  society,  which 
went  against  the  Kendal  branch. — Fortnightly  Return,  October  1873. 


The  Unit  of  Government  99 

authority  of  the  whole  society  before  resisting  any  other 
kind  of  attack.  The  Amalgamated  Society  of  Carpenters 
and  Joiners  has  advanced  a  step  further  in  centralisation 
of  policy.  For  the  last  twenty  years  its  rules  have  expressly 
forbidden  any  branch  to  strike  "  without  first  obtaining  the 
sanction  of  the  executive  council  .  .  .  whether  it  be  for  a 
new  privilege  or  against  an  encroachment  on  existing  ones."  l 
It  is  no  mere  coincidence  that  the  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Carpenters  and  Joiners,  though  younger  than  many  other 
societies  in  the  building  trades,  is  now  the  largest  and  most 
wealthy  of  them  all. 

The  difficulties  that  beset  the  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Engineers  and  the  Operative  Bricklayers'  Society  have  been 
overcome  by  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  a  union 
which  has  found  a  way  to  combine  efficient  administration 
of  friendly  benefits  with  a  strong  and  uniform  trade  policy. 
Here  the  problem  has  been  solved  by  an  absolute  separa- 
tion, both  in  name  and  in  application,  between  the  trade 
and  friendly  benefits.  The  "  donation  benefit "  for  the 
support  of  the  unemployed  is  restricted  to  "  a  man  thrown 
out  of  employment  through  depression  of  trade  or  other 
causes,"  testified  by  "  a  note  signed  by  the  foreman  or 
by  three  full  members  that  are  working  in  the  shop 
or  yard  he  has  left,"  and  proved  to  the  satisfaction  of 
the  officers  of  the  branch.  This  benefit  cannot  be  given  to 
a  man  leaving  his  employment  on  a  dispute  of  any  kind 
whatsoever.  Strike  pay  is  an  entirely  separate  benefit, 
awarded,  even  in  the  case  of  a  single  workman,  only  by  the 
central  executive,  and  payable  only  upon  its  express  and 
particular  direction.2  It  follows  that,  although  the  branches 
administer  the  friendly  benefits,  they  are  not  allowed  to  deal 
in  any  way  with  trade  matters.  If  any  dispute  arises  between 
an  employer  and  his  workmen,  or  even  between  him  and  one 
of  his  workmen,  the  case  is  at  once  taken  up  by  the  district 
delegate,  an  officer  appointed  by  and  acting  for  the  whole 

1  Rule  28,  sec.  10  of  edition  of  1893,  p.  66. 
2  Rules  of  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers  (Newcastle,  1895). 


ioo  Trade  Union  Structure 

society,  in  constant  communication  with  the  general  secretary 
at  headquarters.  No  workman  may  drop  his  tools,  or  even 
give  notice  to  his  employer,  over  any  question  of  trade 
privileges,  except  with  the  prior  authorisation  of  the  district 
delegate ;  and  to  make  doubly  sure  that  this  law  shall  be 
implicitly  obeyed,  not  a  penny  of  benefit  may  be  paid  by 
the  branch  in  any  such  case,  except  on  the  express  direction 
of  the  central  executive. 

Nevertheless,  the  Trade  Union  branch,  even  in  the  most 
centralised  society,  continues  to  fulfil  an  indispensable  function 
in  Trade  Union  administration.  As  an  association  for  mutual 
insurance,  for  the  provision  of  sick  pay,  funeral  expenses,  and 
superannuation  allowance,  the  Trade  Union,  like  the  friendly 
society,  governs  its  action  by  definite  rules  and  fixed  scales 
of  benefit,  which  are  nowadays  settled  as  an  act  of  legisla- 
tion by  the  society  as  a  whole.  Even  the  Out  of  Work 
benefit — the  "  Donation  "  or  "  Idle  Money,"  which  none  but 
trade  societies  have  found  it  possible  to  undertake,  is  dealt 
with  in  the  same  manner.  The  printed  constitution  of  the 
typical  modern  union  prescribes  in  minute  detail  what  sums 
are  to  be  paid  for  sickness  or  out  of  work  benefit,  and 
attempts  to  provide  by  elaborate  rules  for  every  possible 
contingency.  The  central  executive  rigidly  insists  on  the 
rules  being  obeyed  to  the  letter,  and  it  might  at  first  seem 
as  if  nothing  had  been  left  for  the  branch  to  do.  This 
is  very  far  from  being  the  case.  To  protect  the  funds 
from  imposition,  local  and  even  personal  knowledge  is 
indispensable.  Is  a  man  sick  or  malingering  ?  Has  an 
unemployed  member  lost  his  situation  through  slackness  of 
his  employer's  business  or  slackness  of  his  own  energy? 
These  are  questions  that  can  best  be  answered  by  men 
who  have  worked  with  him  in  the  factory,  know  the 
foreman  who  has  dismissed  him,  and  the  employer 
who  has  refused  to  take  him  on,  and  are  acquainted 
with  the  whole  circumstances  of  his  life.  Here  we  find 
the  practical  utility  which  has  kept  the  Trade  Union 
branch  alive  as  a  vital  part  of  Trade  Union  organisation. 


The  Unit  of  Government  101 

It  serves  as  a  jury  for  determining,  not  questions  of  policy, 
but  issues  of  fact.1 

And  if  for  a  moment  we  leave  the  question  of  local  self- 
government,  and  consider  all  the  functions  of  the  branch,  we 
shall  recognise  the  practical  convenience  of  this  institution 
even  in  the  most  highly  centralised  society.  It  is  no  small 
gain  in  a  democratic  organisation  to  have  insured  the  regular 
meeting  together  of  the  great  bulk  of  the  members,  under 
conditions  which  lead  directly  to  the  discussion  of  their 
common  needs.  Nor  is  the  educational  value  of  the  branch 
meeting  its  only  justification.  In  every  Trade  Union,  whether 
governed  by  the  Referendum  or  by  a  Representative  Assembly, 

1  The  utility  of  this  jury  system,  if  we  may  so  describe  the  branch  function, 
may  be  gathered  from  the  experience  of  other  benefit  organisations.  It  is,  to 
begin  with,  significant  that  the  great  industrial  insurance  companies  and  collecting 
societies,  with  their  millions  of  working-class  customers,  and  their  ubiquitous 
network  of  paid  officials,  but  without  a  jury  system,  find  it  financially  impossible 
to  undertake  to  give  even  sick  pay,  let  alone  out  of  work  benefit.  The  Prudential 
Assurance  Company,  the  largest  and  best  managed  of  them  all,  began  to  do  so, 
but  had  to  abandon  it  because,  as  the  secretary  told  the  Royal  Commission  on 
Friendly  Societies  in  1873,  "after  five  years'  experience  we  found  we  were 
unable  to  cope  with  the  fraud  that  was  practised."  Among  friendly  societies 
proper,  in  which  sick  benefit  is  the  main  feature,  it  is  instructive  to  find  that 
it  is  among  the  Foresters  and  Oddfellows,  where  each  court  or  lodge  is  financially 
autonomous,  that  the  rate  of  sickness  is  lowest.  One  interesting  society,  the 
Rational  Sick  and  Burial  Association  (established  in  1837  by  Robert  Owen  and 
his  "Rational  Religionists"),  is  organised  exactly  like  a  national  amalgamated 
Trade  Union,  with  branches  administering  benefits  payable  from  a  common  fund. 
In  this  society,  as  we  gather,  the  rate  of  sickness  is  slightly  greater  than  in  the 
Affiliated  Orders,  where  each  lodge  not  only  decides  on  whether  benefit  shall  be 
given,  but  also  has  itself  to  find  the  money.  Finally,  when  we  come  to  the 
Hearts  of  Oak  Benefit  Society,  the  largest  and  most  efficient  of  the  centralised 
friendly  societies  having  no  branches  at  all,  and  dispensing  all  benefits  from  the 
head  office,  we  find  the  rate  of  sickness  habitually  far  in  excess  of  the  experience 
of  the  Foi-esters  or  the  Oddfellows,  or  even  of  the  Rationals,  an  excess  due, 
according  to  the  repeated  declarations  of  the  actuary,  to  nothing  but  inadequate 
provision  against  fraud  and  malingering.  During  the  eight  years  1884-91,  for 
instance,  the  "expected  sickness,"  according  to  the  1866-70  experience  of  the 
Manchester  Unity  of  Oddfellows  (all  districts),  was  1,111,553  weeks;  the  actual 
weeks  for  which  benefit  was  drawn  numbered  no  fewer  than  1,452,106,  an 
excess  of  over  30  per  cent  (An  Enquiry  into  the  Methods,  etc.,  of  a  Friendly 
Society,  by  R.  P.  Hardy,  1894,  p.  36).  "Centralised  societies,"  says  the 
Rev.  Frome  Wilkinson,  "  will  never  be  able  to  avoid  being  imposed  upon  ;  not 
so,  however,  a  well-regulated  branch  of  an  affiliated  society  with  its  machinery  in 
good  working  order"  (The  Friendly  Societies  Movement,  p.  193).  See  also 
"  Fifty  Years  of  Friendly  Society  Progress,"  by  the  same  author,  in  the  Oddfellow? 
Magazine  for  1888. 


tO2  Trade  Union  Strucfaire 

the  branch  forms  an  integral  part  of  the  legislative  machinery. 
If  the  laws  are  made  by  the  votes  of  the  members,  it  is 
the  branch  meeting  which  is  the  deliberative  assembly,  and 
usually  also  the  polling  place.  When  the  society  enjoys 
fully  developed  representative  institutions,  the  branch  becomes 
at  once  a  natural  and  convenient  electoral  division,  and 
supplies,  what  is  so  sorely  needed  in  political  democracy,  a 
means  by  which  the  representative  must  regularly  meet  every 
section  of  his  constituents.  In  other  trades  it  is  common  to 
require  that  no  important  alteration  of  the  society's  rules  shall 
be  put  before  the  Representative  Assembly  until  it  has  been 
first  discussed,  and  sometimes  voted  on,  by  one  or  more  of 
the  branches.  In  attending  branch  meetings  we  have  found 
most  interesting  that  part  of  the  evening  which  is  taken  up 
with  the  reports  made  by  the  branch  representatives  on  the 
local  Trades  Council,  on  a  district  or  joint  committee  of  the 
trade,  or  in  the  Representative  Assembly  of  the  society  itself. 
It  has  often  occurred  to  us  how  much  it  would  enliven  and 
invigorate  political  democracy  if  the  member  of  Parliament 
or  the  Town  Councillor  had  habitually  to  report  to,  and 
discuss  with,  every  section  of  his  constituents,  supporters  and 
opponents  alike,  all  the  public  business  in  which  they  were 
interested.  Quite  apart,  therefore,  from  any  administrative 
functions,  organisation  by  branches  has  manifold  uses,  even 
in  the  most  centralised  society.  But  these  uses  have  little 
connection  with  the  problem  of  centralisation  and  local 
autonomy.  In  all  these  respects  the  branches  are  not  separate 
units  of  government,  but  constitute,  in  effect,  a  single  mass 
meeting  of  members,  geographically  sliced  up  into  aggregates 
of  convenient  size. 

Thus,  in  the  vexed  problem  of  how  to  divide  ad- 
ministration between  central  and  local  authorities,  Trade 
Union  experience  affords  no  guide,  either  to  other  volun- 
tary associations  or  to  political  democracy.  The  extreme 
centralisation  of  finance  and  policy,  which  the  Trade  Union 
has  found  to  be  a  condition  of  efficiency,  has  been  forced 
upon  it  by  the  unique  character  of  its  functions.  The  lavish 


Interunion  Relations  105 

a  cotton-spinning  mill,  with  40  pairs  of  mules,  will  employ 
about  90  cardroom  operatives,  mostly  women,  the  men  earn- 
ing from  1 8s.  to  305.  per  week  and  the  women  123.  6d.  to 
1 93.  6d. ;  40  adult  male  mule-spinners,  earning,  by  piecework, 
from  303.  to  503.  per  week  ;  80  boys  and  men  as  piecers, 
engaged  and  paid  by  the  mule-spinners  at  6s.  6d.  to  2os.  per 
week  ;  and  2  overlookers  with  weekly  salaries  of  425.  and 
upwards.  The  adjacent  cotton -weaving  shed,  with  800 
looms,  will  employ  about  260  male  and  female  weavers,  paid 
by  the  piece  and  earning  from  143.  to  2os.  per  week  ;  8 
overlookers  (men),  paid  by  a  percentage  on  the  weavers' 
earnings,  and  getting  323.  to  423.  per  week  ;  10  twisters  and 
drawers,  earning  at  piecework  255.  to  323.  per  week;  5 
warpers  and  beamers  working  by  the  piece  and  making  from 
2 os.  to  303.  per  week  ;  3  or  4  tapesizers  with  a  fixed  weekly 
wage  of  425.  per  week  ;  a  number  of  children  varying  from 
I  to  50,  employed  by  the  weavers  as  tenters,  and  paid  small 
sums  ;  and  a  manager  over  the  whole  with  a  salary  of  £200 
or  £300  per  annum.1 

All  these  operatives  may  be  engaged  by  a  single  em- 
ployer, work  upon  the  same  raw  material,  and  produce  for 
the  same  market.      They  have  obviously  many  interests  in 
common.     But  for  all  that  they  do  not  form  a  simple  unit  of 
government.    It  is  impossible  to  devise  any  constitution  which 
would  enable  these  six  or  more  classes  of  cotton  operatives 
to  form  an  amalgamated  union,  having  a  common  policy,  a 
common  purse,  a  common  executive,  and  a  common  staff  of 
officials,  without  sacrificing  the  financial  and  trade  interest  of 
one,  or  even  all  of  the  different  sections.      It  suits  the  well- 
c    paid   sections,   such    as  the   Spinners,  Tapesizers,  Beamers, 
^  Twisters,  Drawers,  and   Overlookers,  to  pay  a  high  weekly 
als(contribution,   which   would    be    beyond    the   means    of   the 
paitTardroom  Operatives  and  the  Weavers.     But  the  manner  in 
ls>  a%ich   each    section    desires  to  apply  its  funds  varies  even 


execut 


Compare  the  still  more  detailed  classification  of  workers  incidentally  given 
e  Board  of  Trade  Keport  by  Miss  Collet  on  Ike  Statistics  of  Employment 
/omen  and  Girls,  C.  7564,  1894. 


106  Trade  Union  Structure 

more  than  their  amount.  The  Tapesizers,  deriving  their 
strategic  strength  from  their  highly  specialised  skill,  the 
impossibility  of  replacing  them,  and  the  small  proportion 
which  their  wages  bear  to  the  total  cost  of  production,  can 
afford  to  spend  their  funds  on  ample  sick  and  funeral  benefits. 
With  a  uniform  time  rate  in  each  district,  and  few  occasions 
for  dispute  with  their  employers,  they  need  no  offices  or 
salaried  officials  whatsoever.  It  pays  the  Spinners  and 
Weavers,  on  the  other  hand,  to  maintain  a  highly  skilled 
professional  staff  for  the  purpose  of  computing  and  maintain- 
ing their  earnings  under  the  complicated  lists  of  piecework 
prices.  But  the  Weavers  stand  at  the  disadvantage  of  need- 
ing also  a  large  staff  of  paid  collectors  to  secure  the  regular 
payment  of  contributions  from  the  girls  and  married  women, 
who  are  indisposed  to  bring  their  weekly  pence  to  the  public- 
house  in  which  the  branch  meeting  is  still  frequently  held. 
This  applies  also  to  the  Cardroom  Operatives,  but  these, 
working  usually  at  time  rates,  do  not  need  the  weavers'  skilled 
calculator.  The  Beamers,  Twisters,  and  Drawers,  on  the  one 
hand,  and  the  Overlookers  on  the  other,  have  again  their  own 
peculiarities.  To  unite,  in  any  common  scheme  of  contri- 
butions and  benefits,  classes  so  diverse  in  their  means  and 
requirements,  appears  absolutely  impossible.  Still  more 
difficult  would  it  be  to  provide  for  the  effective  representation 
upon  a  common  executive  of  sections  so  different  in  numerical 
strength.  Not  to  mention  the  Tapesizers  and  Overlookers, 
who  must  be  completely  submerged  by  the  rest,  it  would  be 
difficult  to  induce  the  19,000  well-paid,  well-officered,  and 
well-disciplined  Spinners  to  submit  their  trade  policy  to  the 
decision  of  the  22,000  ill-paid  Cardroom  Operatives  or  the 
85,000  Weavers,  of  whom  two-thirds  are  women.  On  the 
other  hand,  the  Weavers  would  not  permanently  forego  the 
advantage  of  their  overwhelming  superiority  in  numbers,  nor 
would  the  Spinners  allow  the  Tapesizers  an  equal  voice  with 
themselves.  But  even  if  a  representative  executive  could,  by 
some  device,  be  got  together,  it  would  not  form  a  fit  body 
to  decide  the  technical  questions  peculiar  to  each  class. 


Interunion  Relations  107 

On  each  point  as  it  arose,  the  experts  would  be  in  a 
minority,  and  the  decisions,  -whatever  their  justice,  would 
invariably  cause  dissatisfaction  to  one  section  or  another. 
Moreover,  quite  apart  from  technical  details,  the  moments  of 
strategic  advantage  differ  from  section  to  section.  It  may 
suit  the  Spinners  to  move  for  an  advance,  at  a  time  when  the 
weaving  trade  is  depressed,  and  both  will  be  more  ready  to 
move  than  the  Overlookers.  The  Tapesizers,  on  the  other 
hand,  will  prefer,  to  any  overt  strike,  the  silent  withdrawal  of 
one  man  after  another  from  a  recalcitrant  employer,  until  he 
is  ready  to  offer  the  Trade  Union  terms.  It  is  obvious  that 
a  council  representing  such  diverse  elements  would  find  it 
extremely  difficult  to  maintain  an  active  and  consistent 
course.  On  the  other  hand,  all  the  sections  of  Cotton 
Operatives  have  manifold  interests  in  common.  Every 
factory  act  regulating  the  sanitation,  hours  of  labor, 
machinery,  age  of  children,  and  inspection  of  factories, 
directly  or  indirectly  concerns  every  worker  in  the  mill. 
Such  industrial  dislocations  as  Liverpool  "  cotton  corners," 
or  the  employers'  mutual  agreement  to  reduce  stocks  by 
working  short  time,  affect  all  alike.  The  policy  of  the 
Indian  Secretary,  the  Minister  of  Education,  or  the  Chan- 
cellor of  the  Exchequer,  may,  any  moment,  touch  them  all 
on  a  vital  point.  If,  therefore,  the  Cotton  Operatives  are  to 
have  any  effective  voice  in  regulating  these  essentially  trade 
matters,  their  organisation  must  in  some  form  be  co-extensive 
with  the  whole  cotton  industry. 

Another  instance  of  these  difficulties  is  presented  by  the 
great  industry  of  engineering.  A  century  ago  the  small 
skilled  class  of  millwrights  executed  every  kind  of  engineer- 
ing operation,  from  making  the  wooden  patterns  to  erecting 
in  the  mill  the  machines  which  had  been  constructed  by 
their  own  hands.  The  enormous  expansion  of  the  engineer^ 
ing  industry  has  long  since  brought  about  a  division  of 
labor,  and  the  mechanics  in  a  great  engineering  establish- 
ment to-day  are  divided  into  numerous  distinct  classes  of 
workers,  who  are  rarely  able  to  do  each  other's  work.  The 


io8  Trade  Union  Structure 

pattern-makers,  working  in  wood,  have  become  sharply 
marked  off  from  the  boilermakers  and  the  ironfounders. 
The  smiths,  again,  are  distinguished  from  the  fitters,  turners, 
and  erectors.  Another  form  of  specialisation  has  arisen  with 
the  increased  use  of  other  metals  than  iron  and  steel,  and 
we  have  brass -founders,  brass-finishers,  and  coppersmiths. 
Each  generation  sees  a  great  development  in  the  use  of 
machines  to  make  machines,  so  that  a  modern  engineering 
shop,  in  addition  to  the  time-honored  lathe,  includes  a  be- 
wildering variety  of  drilling,  shaping,  boring,  planing,  slotting, 
milling,  and  other  machines,  attended  by  wholly  new  classes 
of  machine-minders  and  tool-makers,  displaying  every  grade 
of  skill.  Finally,  we  have  such  new  kinds  of  work,  with  new 
classes  of  specialists,  as  are  involved  in  the  innumerable 
applications  of  iron  and  steel  in  modern  civilisation,  such  as 
iron  ships  and  bridges,  ordnance  and  armour-plating,  hydraulic 
apparatus  and  electric-lighting,  sewing-machines  and  bicycles. 
To  discover  the  exact  limits  of  a  "  trade  "  in  these  closely 
related  but  varied  occupations  is  a  task  of  supreme  difficulty. 
All  are  working  in  the  same  industry,  and  in  the  large 
establishments  of  to-day,  all  may  be  engaged  by  a  single 
employer.  The  same  recurring  waves  of  expansion  and 
contraction  sooner  or  later  affect  all  alike.  On  the  other 
hand,  there  exist  between  the  separate  occupations  great 
varieties  of  methods  of  remuneration,  standard  earnings,  and 
strategic  position.  The  strictly  -  apprenticed  boilermakers 
(shipyard  platers)  working  in  compact  groups,  at  co-operative 
piecework,  earning  sometimes  as  much  as  a  pound  a  day, 
find  it  advantageous  in  good  times  to  roll  up,  by  large  sub- 
scriptions, a  huge  reserve  fund,  to  maintain  a  staff  of  special 
trade  officers  to  arrange  their  piecework  prices  at  every  port, 
and  to  provide  handsomely  for  their  recurring  periods  of 
trade  depression.  At  the  other  end  of  the  scale  we  have  the 
intelligent  laborer  become  an  automatic  machine-minder, 
securing  relative  continuity  of  low-paid  employment  by 
working  any  simple  machine  in  any  kind  of  engineering 
establishment,  and  interested  mainly  in  the  opening  of  every 


Interunion  Relations  109 

operation  to  the  quickwitted  outsider.  The  pattern-maker 
again,  working  in  wood,  at  a  high  time  rate,  has  little  in 
common  with  the  piece-working  smith  at  the  forge.  When 
trade  begins  to  improve,  the  pattern-makers,  followed  by  the 
ironfounders,  will  be  busy  long  before  the  smiths,  fitters, 
and  turners,  and,  if  they  wish  to  recover  the  wages  lost  in 
the  previous  depression,  must  move  for  an  advance  whilst 
all  the  rest  of  the  engineering  industry  is  still  on  short  time. 
Finally,  there  is  the  difficulty  of  the  method  and  basis  of 
representation.  Shall  the  government  be  centred  in  an  iron 
shipbuilding  port,  where  the  boilermakers  would  be  supreme, 
or  in  an  inland  engineering  centre,  when  the  fitters  and 
turners  would  have  an  equally  great  preponderance  ?  How 
can  the  tiny  groups  of  pattern-makers,  dispersed  over  the 
whole  kingdom,  get  their  separate  interests  attended  to  amid 
the  overwhelming  majorities  of  the  other  classes  ?  Any 
attempt  to  represent,  upon  an  executive  council,  each  dis- 
tinct occupation,  let  alone  each  great  centre,  must  either 
ignore  all  proportional  considerations,  or  involve  the  forma- 
tion of  a  body  of  impossible  dimensions  and  costliness. 

We  see,  therefore,  that  within  the  circle  of  what  is  usually 
called  a  trade,  there  are  often  smaller  circles  of  specialised 
classes  of  workmen,  each  sufficiently  distinctive  in  character 
to  claim  separate  consideration.  The  first  idea  is  always  to 
cut  the  Gordian  knot  by  ignoring  these  differences,  and 
making  the  larger  circle  the  unit  of  government.  So  fas- 
cinating is  this  idea  of  "  amalgamation "  that  it  has  been 
tried  in  almost  every  industry.  The  reader  of  the  History 
of  Trade  Unionism  will  remember  the  remarkable  attempt 
in  1 833-34  to  form  a  national  "Builders'  Union,"  to  com- 
prise the  seven  different  branches  of  building  operatives. 
The  same  years  saw  a  succession  of  general  unions  in  the 
cloth-making  industry.  In  1844,  and  again  in  1863,  the 
coalminers  sought  to  combine  in  one  amalgamated  union 
every  person  employed  in  or  about  the  mines,  from  one  end 
of  the  kingdom  to  the  other.  The  "  Iron  Trades "  again 
were,  between  1840  and  1850,  the  subject  of  innumerable 


i  io  Trade  Union  Structure 

local  projects  of  amalgamation,  in  which  not  only  the  "  Five 
Trades  of  Mechanism,"  but  also  the  Boilermakers  and  the 
Ironfounders  were  all  to  be  included.  We  need  not  describe 
the  failure  of  all  these  attempts.  More  can,  perhaps,  be 
learnt  from  the  experience  of  the  great  modern  instance,  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers. 

It  does  not  seem  to  have  occurred  to  William  Newton, 
when  he  launched  this  famous  amalgamation,  that  any  diffi- 
culty could  arise  as  to  the  classes  of  workers  to  be  included. 
What  he  was  primarily  concerned  about  was  to  merge  in 
one  national  organisation  all  the  various  local  societies  of 
engineering  mechanics,  whether  pattern-makers,  smiths,  turners, 
fitters,  or  erectors,  working  either  in  iron  or  brass.  But 
"  sectionalism  "  stood,  from  the  very  first,  in  the  way.  The 
various  local  clubs  of  Smiths  and  Pattern-makers  objected 
strongly  to  sink  their  individuality  in  a  general  engineers' 
union.  In  the  same  way,  the  more  exclusive  Steam-Engine 
Makers'  Society,  in  which  millwrights,  fitters,  and  turners 
predominated,  refused  to  merge  itself  in  the  wider  organisa- 
tion. To  Newton  and  Allan  all  these  objections  seemed  to 
arise  from  the  natural  reluctance  of  local  clubs  to  lose  their 
individuality  in  a  national  union.  This  dislike,  as  they 
rightly  felt,  was  destined  to  give  way  before  the  superior 
advantages  of  national  combination.  But  subsequent  ex- 
perience has  shown  that  the  resistance  to  the  amalgamation 
was  due  to  more  permanent  causes.  The  merely  local 
societies  dropped  in,  one  by  one,  to  their  greater  rival.  But 
this  only  revealed  a  more  serious  cleavage.  The  present 
rivals  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  are,  not  any 
local  engineers'  clubs,  but  national  societies  each  claiming 
the  exclusive  allegiance  of  different  sections  of  the  trade. 
The  pattern-makers,  for  instance,  came  to  the  conclusion  in 
1872  that  their  interests  were  neglected  in  the  Amalgamated 
Society  of  Engineers,  and  formed  the  United  Pattern-makers' 
Association,  which  now  includes  a  large  and  increasing 
majority  of  this  highly  skilled  class.  The  Associated  Society 
of  Blacksmiths,  originally  a  Glasgow  local  club,  now  dominates 


Interunion  Relations  \  1 1 

its   particular   section   of  the    trade   on   the    Clyde    and    in 
Belfast,  and  has  branches  in   the   North  of  England.      The 
Brass-workers,  the  Coppersmiths,  and  the   Machine-minders 
have  now  all  their  own  societies  of  national  extent.     The 
result  has  been  that  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers 
does  not  realise  Newton's  idea  as  regards  any  section  what- 
ever.    The  Boilermakers,  who  refused  to  have  anything  to 
do  with  amalgamation,  and  who  have  persistently  put  their 
energy  into  organising  their  own  special  craft,  have  succeeded, 
as  we  have  mentioned,  in  forming  one  undivided,  consolidated, 
and  centralised  society  for  the  entire  kingdom.      Very  different 
is  the  condition  of  the  engineers.      Neither  the  fitters  nor  the 
smiths,  the  pattern-makers   nor   the   machine-minders,    the 
brass-workers   nor  the  coppersmiths,  are   united   in  any  one 
society,  or  able  to  maintain  a  uniform  trade  policy,  even  for 
their  own  section  of  the  industry.     For  all  this  confusion,  the 
enthusiastic  adherents  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  have  gone 
on  preaching  the  one  remedy  of  an  ever-wider  amalgama- 
tion.   "  The  future  basis  of  the  Amalgamated  Society,"  urged 
Mr.  Tom  Mann  in  1891,  "  must  be  one  that  will  admit  every 
workman  engaged  in  connection  with  the  engineering  trades, 
and  who  is  called  upon  to  exhibit  mechanical  skill  in  the 
performance    of   his    labor.      This   would   include    men    on 
milling  and  drilling  machines,  tool-makers,  die-sinkers,  and 
electrical  engineers,  and  it  would  make  it  necessary  to  have 
the  requisite  staff  at  the  general  office  to  cater  for  so  large  a 
constituency,  as  there  are  at  least  250,000  men  engaged  in 
the  engineering' and  machine  trades  of  the  United  Kingdom, 
and  the  work  of  organising  this  body  must  be  undertaken 
by  the  A.  S.  E." *      Somewhat   against   the   advice  of  the 
more  experienced  officials,  successive  delegate  meetings  have 
included   within   the  society  one  section  of  workmen   after 
another.     At  the  delegate  meeting  of   1892,  which  opened 
the  society  to  practically  every  competent  workman  in  the 
most  miscellaneous  engineering   establishment,  it   was  even 

1  Address  to  the  East  End  Institute  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers, 
London,  in  Trade  Unionist ',  loth  October  1891, 


1 1 2  Trade  Union  Structure 

urged  by  some  branches  that  the  boundaries  should  be 
still  further  enlarged,  so  as  to  permit  the  absorption  of 
plumbers  and  ironfounders.  This  proposal  was  with  some 
reluctance  rejected,  but  only  on  the  ground  that  it  would 
have  brought  the  Amalgamation  into  immediate  collision 
with  the  16,278  members  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Iron- 
founders  (established  1809);  and  with  the  compact  and 
militant  United  Operative  Plumbers'  Society  (established 
1848,  membership  8758),  rivals  too  powerful  to  be  lightly 
encountered.  Each  successive  widening  of  the  amalgama- 
tion brings  it,  in  fact,  into  conflict  with  a  larger  number  of 
other  unions,  who  become  its  embittered  enemies.  The  very 
competition  between  rival  societies  which  Newton's  amal- 
gamation was  intended  to  supersede,  has,  through  this  all- 
inclusive  policy  itself,  been  rendered  more  intense  and 
intractable. 

And  here  it  is  imperative  that  the  reader  should  fully 
appreciate  the  disastrous  effect  of  this  competition  and  rivalry 
between  separate  Trade  Unions.  The  evil  will  be  equally 
apparent  whether  we  regard  the  Trade  Union  merely  as  a 
friendly  society  for  insuring  the  weekly  wage-earner  against 
loss  of  livelihood  through  sickness,  old  age,  and  depression 
of  trade,  or  as  a  militant  organisation  for  enabling  the 
manual  worker  to  obtain  better  conditions  from  the  capitalist 
employer. 

Let  us  consider  first  the  side  of  Trade  Unionism  which 
has,  from  the  outset,  been  universally  praised  and  admired, 
the  "  ancient  and  most  laudable  custom  for  divers  artists 
within  the  United  Kingdom  to  meet  and  form  themselves 
into  societies  for  the  sole  purpose  of  assisting  each  other  in 
cases  of  sickness;  old  age,  and  other  infirmities,  and  for  the 
burial  of  their  dead."  l  Now,  whatever  weight  may  be  given, 
in  matters  of  commerce,  to  the  maxim  caveat  emptor — how- 
ever thoroughly  we  may  rely,  as  regards  articles  of  personal 
consumption,  on  the  buyer's  watchfulness  over  his  own 

1  Preamble  to  Rules  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Ironmongers   (Manchester, 
1809),  and  to  those  of  many  other  unions  of  this  epoch. 


Interunion  Relations  1 1 3 

interests — it  is  indisputable  that,  in  the  whole  realm  of 
insurance,  competition  does  practically  nothing  to  promote 
efficiency.  The  assumption  which  underlies  the  faith  in 
unrestricted  competition  is  that  the  consumer  is  competent 
to  judge  of  the  quality  of  what  he  pays  for,  or  that  he  will  at 
any  rate  become  so  in  the  act  of  consumption.  In  matters 
of  financial  insurance  no  such  assumption  can  reasonably  be 
maintained.  Apart  from  the  dangers  of  irregularities  and 
defalcations,  the  whole  question  of  efficiency  or  inefficiency 
in  friendly  society  administration  is  bound  up  with  the 
selection  of  proper  actuarial  data,  the  collection  and  verifica- 
tion of  the  society's  own  actuarial  experience,  and  the  con- 
sequent fixing  of  the  due  rates  of  contribution  and  benefits. 
When  rival  societies  bid  against  each  other  for  members, 
competition  inevitably  takes  the  form,  either  of  offering  the 
common  benefits  at  a  lower  rate,  or  of  promising  extravagant 
benefits  at  the  common  rate  of  subscription.  The  ordinary 
man,  innocent  of  actuarial  science,  is  totally  unable  to 
appreciate  the  merits  of  the  rival  scales  put  before  him. 
To  the  raw  recruit  the  smallness  of  the  weekly  levy  offers 
an  almost  irresistible  attraction.  Nor  does  such  illegitimate 
competition  between  societies  work,  as  might  be  supposed, 
its  own  cure.  The  club  charging  rates  insufficient  to  meet 
its  liabilities  will,  it  is  true,  in  the  end  bring  about  its  own 
destruction.  But  the  actuarial  nemesis  is  slow  to  arrive,  as 
many  years  must  elapse  before  the  full  measure  of  the 
liability  for  death  claims  and  superannuation  allowances 
can  be  tested.  And  when  the  inevitable  collapse  comes, 
the  prudent  society  gains  little  by  the  dissolution  of  its 
unsound  rival.  A  club  which  has  failed  to  meet  its  engage- 
ments, and  has  been  broken  up,  leaves  those  who  have  been 
its  members  suspicious  of  all  forms  of  organisation  and 
indisposed  to  renew  their  contributions.  The  payment  for 
some  time  of  high  benefits  in  return  for  low  subscriptions 
will  have  falsified  the  standard  of  expectation.  Those  who 
have  lost  their  money  ascribe  the  failure  to  the  dishonesty 
or  incapacity  of  the  officers,  to  the  workmen's  lack  of  loyalty, 
VOL.  I  I 


i  1 4  Trade  Union  Structure 

to  any  cause,  indeed,  rather  than  to  their  own  unreasonable- 
ness in  expecting  a  shilling's  worth  of  benefits  for  a  sixpenny 
contribution. 

In  the  case  of  Friendly  Societies  proper,  and  in  that  of 
Insurance  Companies,  the  untrustworthiness  of  competition 
as  a  guarantee  of  financial  efficiency  has  been  fully  recog- 
nised by  the  community,  and  dealt  with  by  the  legislature.1 
Trade  Unions,  however,  have,  for  good  and  sufficient  reasons, 
been  left  outside  the  scope  of  these  provisions.2  But,  as  a 
matter  of  fact,  competition  between  Trade  Unions  on  their 
benefit  club  side  is  even  more  injurious  to  their  soundness 
than  it  is  to  Friendly  Societies  proper,  Dealing  as  they  do, 
not  with  a  specially  selected  class  of  thrifty  citizens,  but 
with  the  whole  body  of  men  in  their  trade  ;  unable,  owing  to 
their  other  functions,  to  concentrate  their  members'  attention 
upon  the  actuarial  side  of  their  affairs  ;  and  destitute  of  any 
authoritative  data  or  scientific  calculation  for  such  benefits 
as  Out  of  Work  pay,  Trade  Unions  must  always  find  it 
specially  difficult  to  resist  a  demand  for  increase  of  benefits,  or 
lowering  of  contribution.  If  two  unions  are  competing  for  the 
same  class  of  members,  the  pressure  becomes  irresistible. 

The  history  of  Trade  Unionism  is  one  long  illustration  of 
this  argument.  In  one  trade  after  another  we  watch  the 
cropping  up  of  "  mushroom  unions,"  their  heated  rivalry 

1  It  is  unnecessary  for  us  to  do  more  than  refer  to  the  long  series  of  statutes, 
beginning  in   1786,  which  provide  for  the  registration,  publication  of  accounts, 
public  audit,  and  even  compulsory  valuation  of  Friendly  Societies  and  Industrial 
Insurance  Companies.     By  every  means,  short  of  direct  prohibition,  the  State 
now  seeks  to  put  obstacles  in  the  way  of  "under-cutting,"  and,  to  use  the  words 
of  Mr.    Reuben  Watson  before   the  Select   Committee   on   National   Provident 
Insurance  in   1885  (Question  893),  discourages  "the  formation  of  new  societies 
on  the  unsound  principles  of  former  times."     Within  the  two  great  "affiliated 
orders  "  of  Oddfellows  and  Foresters,  which  together  comprise  at  least  half  the 
friendly  society  world,  the  legal  requirements  are  backed  by  an  absolute  prohibi- 
tion to  open  any  new  lodge  or  court  without  adopting,  as  a  minimum,  the  definitely 
approved  scale  of  contributions  and  benefits.      Even  with  regard  to  middle-class 
life  assurance  companies,  Parliament  has  not  only  insisted  on  a  specific  account- 
keeping  and  publication  of  financial  position,  but  has,  since  1872,  practically 
stopped  the  uprising  of  additional  competitors,  by  requiring  a  deposit  of  ^"20,000 
from  any  new  company  before  business  can  be  begun. 

2  See  the  chapter  on  "The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance." 


Inierunion  Relations  1 1 5 

with  the  older  organisations,  and  consequent  mad  race  for 
members  ;  and  finally,  after  a  few  years  of  unstable  existence, 
their  ignoble  bankruptcy  and  dissolution.  Meanwhile  the 
responsible  officials  of  the  older  societies  will  have  been 
struggling  with  their  own  "  Delegate  Meetings  "  and  "  Revising 
Committees,"  to  maintain  a  relatively  sound  scale  of  con- 
tributions and  benefits.  Any  attempt  at  financial  improve- 
ment will  have  been  checked  by  the  representations  of  the 
branch  officers  that  the  only  result  would  be  to  divert  all  the 
recruits  to  their  rasher  and  more  open-handed  competitors. 
The  records  of  every  important  union  contain  bitter 
complaints  of  this  injurious  competition.  The  Friendly 
Society  of  Ironfounders,  for  instance,  which  dates  from  1809, 
is  one  of  the  oldest  and  most  firmly  established  Trade 
Unions.  Its  16,000  members  include  an  overwhelming 
majority  of  the  competent  ironmoulders  in  England,  Ireland, 
and  Wales.  For  over  sixty  years  it  has  collected  and 
preserved  admirable  statistical  data  of  the  cost  of  its  various 
benefits,  to  provide  for  which  it  maintains  a  relatively  high 
rate  of  contribution  and  levies.  In  August  1891,  a  leading 
member  called  attention  to  the  touting  for  membership 
that  was  going  on  among  his  trade  in  certain  districts. 
"  I  have  now  noticed,"  he  concludes,  "  three  distinct 
societies  that  enter  moulders  (ironfounders)  who  are 
eligible  to  join  us.  They  offer,  more  or  less,  a  high  rate 
of  benefit  at  a  low  rate  of  contribution^  Whether  they 
are  likely  to  fulfil  their  promises  I  leave  to  the  judgment  of 
any  thoughtful  man  who  will  sit  down  and  compare  their 
rates  of  contribution  and  benefits  with  the  statistical  figures 
of  our  society,  as  shown  continually  in  the  annual  reports. 
Those  figures  have  been  arrived  at  by  experience,  which  is 
•the  truest  basis  of  calculation  for  the  future,  and  I  would 
commend  them  to  the  notice  of  all  who  set  themselves  the 
task  of  computing  the  maximum  rate  of  benefit  to  be 
obtained  at  the  minimum  rate  of  subscription."  J  Nor  was 

1  Letter  from  H.  G.  Percival  in  the  Monthly  Report  of  t fie  Friendly  Society 
of  Ironfounders  (August  1891),  pp.  18-2 1. 


1 1 6  Trade  Union  Structure 

this  warning  unneeded.  When,  in  the  very  next  month,  the 
Ironfounders  met  in  delegate  meeting  to  revise  their  rules, 
branch  after  branch  suggested,  in  order  to  outstrip  the 
attractions  of  their  extravagant  rivals,  an  increase  of 
benefits,  without  any  addition  to  the  contribution.  Thus 
Gateshead,  Keighley,  and  Greenwich  urged  that  the  Out  of 
Work  benefit  should  be  increased  by  more  than  ten  per 
cent ;  Huddersfield  and  Oldham  sought  to  raise  the  maxi- 
mum sum  receivable  in  any  one  year ;  Barrow,  Halifax, 
and  Liverpool  asked  that  travellers  should  be  allowed 
sixpence  per  night  instead  of  fourpence  ;  Oldham  tried 
largely  to  increase  the  scale  of  superannuation  allowances, 
and  to  raise  the  Accident  Grant  from  ^50  to  ;£ioo  ; 
St.  Helens  and  many  other  branches  demanded  a  ten  per 
cent  increase  of  the  sick  benefit ;  whilst  Brighton,  Keighley, 
and  Wakefield  proposed  to  raise  the  funeral  money  from 
£10  to  £12.  On  the  other  hand,  Chelsea  proposed  a 
reduction  of  the  entrance  fee  by  33  per  cent,  whilst 
Gloucester  sought  to  lower  it  by  one-half ;  Liverpool  would 
take  in  men  up  to  the  age  of  45,  instead  of  stopping  at 
40 ;  and  Wakefield  suggested  the  abandonment  of  any 
medical  examination  at  entrance.1  Fortunately  for  the 
Ironfounders,  their  officers,  with  the  statistical  tables  at 
their  back,  were  able  to  stave  off  most  of  these  pro- 
posals. But  even  responsible  officials  are  forced  to  pay 
heed  to  this  reckless  competition.  Thus  in  1885,  when 
certain  branches  of  the  Steam  -  Engine  Makers'  Society, 
getting  anxious  about  their  old  age,  suggested  that  the 
provision  for  the  superannuation  benefit  should  be  increased, 
the  central  executive  demurred  to  raising  the  contribution, 
pointing  out  "  the  keen  competition  "  for  membership  which 
they  had  to  meet,  "just  as  though  we  were  engaged  in 
commerce.  In  every  workshop,"  they  continue,  "  we  have 
numerous  societies  to  contend  with,  some  of  whose  members 

1  Suggestions  from  Branches  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders  .  .  .  for 
consideration  at  the  Delegate  Meeting  to  be  held  in  September  1891  (London, 
1891). 


Interunion  Relations  1 1 7 

think  that  taking  a  man  from  another  society  and  squeezing 
him  into  theirs  is  a  valiant  act.  Many  cases  will  occur  to 
all,  but  we  give  one  instance.  We  learned  of  the  Pattern- 
makers' Association  taking  members  of  ours  for  an  entrance 
fee  of  55.,  placing  them  in  benefit  at  once,  and  even  giving 
them  credit  for  ten  years'  membership,  should  they  apply  for 
superannuation  in  the  future."  J  These  examples  enable  us 
to  understand  why  it  is  that  the  Trade  Unions  accumulating 
the  largest  reserve  funds  to  meet  their  prospective  liabilities 
are  to  be  found  in  the  trades  in  which  a  single  union  is 
co-extensive  with  the  industry.  Thus,  among  the  larger 
organisations,  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers  with  a 
balance  in  1896  of  £175,000,  or  £4  :  7  :  6  per  head  of  its 
41,000  members,  towers  above  all  other  societies  in  the 
engineering  and  shipbuilding  trades. 

We  have  dwelt  in  some  detail  upon  the  evils  of  com- 
petition between  Trade  Unions  considered  merely  as  benefit 
clubs,  because  this  part  of  their  function  has  secured  universal 
approval.  But  assuming  that  the  workmen  are  right  in 
believing  trade  combination  to  be  economically  useful  to 
them — assuming,  that  is  to  say,  that  the  institution  of  Trade 
Unionism  has  any  justification  at  all — the  case  against  com- 
petition among  unions  becomes  overwhelming  in  strength. 
If  a  trade  is  split  up  among  two  or  more  rival  societies, 
especially  if  these  are  unequal  in  numbers,  scope,  or  the 
character  of  their  members,  there  is  practically  no  possibility 
of  arriving  at  any  common  policy  to  be  pursued  by  all  the 
branches,  or  of  consistently  maintaining  any  course  of  action 
whatsoever.  "The  general  position  of  our  society  in  Liverpool," 
reports  the  District  Delegate  of  the  Amalgamated  Society 
of  Engineers  in  1893,  "is  far  from  satisfactory,  the  work  of 
organising  the  trade  being  rendered  exceptionally  difficult, 
not  only  by  the  existence  of  a  large  non-union  element, 
bwt  by  the  existence  of  a  number  of  sectional  societies. 
Here,  as  elsewhere,  these  small  and  unnecessary  organisations 

1  Steam- Engine  Makers'  Society  ;  Executive  Council  Report  on  Revision  of 
Rules,  25th  July  1885. 


1 1 8  Trade  Union  Structure 

are  the  causes  of  endless  complications  and  inconvenience. 
How  many  of  these  absurd  and  irritating  institutions  actually 
exist  here  I  am  not  yet  in  a  position  to  say,  but  the  following 
are  those  with  which  I  am  at  present  acquainted  :  Smiths  and 
Strikers  (Amalgamated),  Mersey  Shipsmiths,  Steam-Engine 
Makers,  United  Pattern-makers,  Liverpool  Coppersmiths, 
Brass -finishers  (Liverpool),  Brass -finishers  (Birmingham), 
United  Machine  Workers,  Metal  Planers,  National  Engineers. 
All  these  societies  are  naturally  inimical  to  our  own,  yet  how 
long  shall  we  be  able  to  tolerate  their  existence  is  another 
question.  .  .  .  The  Boilermakers  would  never  permit  any 
section  of  their  trade  to  organise  apart  from  them  ;  why  we 
should  do  so  is  a  question  which  will  assuredly  have  to  be 
settled  definitely  sooner  or  later."1  The  "small  and  unnecessary 
organisations  "  naturally  take  a  different  view.  The  general 
secretary  of  the  United  Pattern-makers'  Association,  in  a 
circular  full  of  bitter  complaints  against  the  Amalgamated 
Society  of  Engineers,  thus  describes  the  situation  :  "  For  the 
information  of  those  who  may  not  be  intimately  acquainted 
with  the  engineering  trade,  we  may  explain  that  the  Pattern- 
makers form  almost  the  smallest  section  of  that  trade — the 
organised  portion  being  split  up  into  no  less  than  four 
different  sections  [societies] — the  largest  section  outside  the 
ranks  of  the  United  Pattern-makers'  Association  belonging  to 
the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers.  It  will  be  easily 
understood  that  this  division  makes  it  very  difficult  for  our 
society  to  act  on  the  offensive  with  that  promptitude  which 
is  often  essential  to  the  successful  carrying  out  of  a  particular 
movement,  as  we  have  to  consult  with  and  obtain  the  co- 
operation of  three  societies  other  than  our  own  ;  and  as  our 
trade  in  these  societies  are  in  an  insignificant  minority,  it  is 
perhaps  only  natural  that  so  far  as  the  Amalgamated  Society 
of  Engineers  is  concerned,  legislation  for  the  trades  that 
comprise  the  vast  majority  of  its  members  should  have  a 
priority  over  a  consideration  of  those  questions  which  concern 

1   "  Report  of  Organising  District  Delegate  (No.  2  division)  of  Amalgamated 
Society  of  Engineers"  in  Quarterly  Report  for  quarter  ended  March  1893. 


Interunion  Relations  119 

so  small  a  handful  as  the  Pattern-makers  belonging  to  their 
society."  l  An  actual  example  of  the  everyday  working  life 
of  a  Trade  Union  branch  will  show  how  real  is  the  difficulty 
thus  caused.  "Our  Darlington  members,"  reports  the  Pattern- 
makers' Executive,  "  have  been  engaged  in  a  wages  movement 
which  has  had  in  one  respect  a  most  unsatisfactory  termination. 
The  *  Mais ' 2  and  non-society  men  pledged  themselves  to  assist 
our  members  to  get  the  money  up,  until  the  critical  moment 
arrived  when  notices  were  to  be  given  in.  The  non-society 
element  and  the  *  Mais '  then  formed  an  ignominious  com- 
bination, and  declined  to  go  any  further  in  the  matter,  the 
Darlington  branch  of  the  '  Mais '  writing  our  Secretary  to 
the  effect  that  they  would  not  permit  their  P.M.'s  [Pattern- 
makers] to  strike.  They  only  number  three,  and  the  non- 
society  men  twice  as  many,  so  fortunately  they  could  not  do 
the  cause  very  much  injury.  The  advance  was  conceded  by 
every  firm  excepting  the  Darlington  Iron  and  Steel  Works, 
where  our  men  were  drawn  out,  leaving  two  *  Mais '  and  their 
present  allies,  the  non-society  men,  at  work.  Your  general 
secretary  wrote  the  executive  committee  of  the  '  Mais '  on 
the  subject  over  three  weeks  ago,  but  so  insignificant  a 
matter  as  this  is  apparently  beneath  the  notice  of  this  august 
body,  as  no  reply  has  yet  been  vouchsafed."  3 

Trade  Union  rivalry  has,  however,  a  darker  side.  When 
the  officers  of  the  two  organisations  have  been  touting  for 
members,  and  feeling  keenly  each  other's  competition,  oppor- 
tunities for  friction  and  ill-temper  can  scarcely  fail  to  arise. 
Accusations  will  be  made  on  both  sides  of  disloyalty  and 
unfairness,  which  will  be  echoed  and  warmly  resented  by  the 

1  Circular  of  United  Pattern-makers'  Association  (on  Belfast  dispute),  22nd 
June  1892.     The  same  note   recurs  in  the  Report  of  Proceedings  of  the  Sixth 
Annual  Meeting  of  the  Federation   of  Engineering  and   Shipbuilding  Trades 
(Manchester,  1896).      "As  a  consequence  of  their  present  divided  state,"  said 
Mr.   Mosses,   the  general  secretary  of  the  United    Pattern-makers'  Association, 
at  this  meeting,    "they  had  one  district  going  in  for  advances,  followed  in  a 
haphazard  fashion  by  other  districts  ;  and  one  body  of  men  coming  out  on  strike 
for  the  benefit  of  others  who  remained  at  their  work." 

2  Members  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers. 

3  Monthly  Report  of  the  United  Pattern-makers'  Association,  September  1889. 


1 20  Trade  Union  Structure 

rank  and  file.  Presently  some  dispute  occurs  between  an 
employer  and  the  members  of  one  of  the  unions.  These 
workmen  may  be  dismissed  by  the  employer,  or  withdrawn 
by  order  of  their  own  district  committee.  The  officers  of  the 
rival  union  soon  hear  of  the  vacancies  from  the  firm  in 
question.  Members  of  their  own  society  are  walking  the 
streets  in  search  of  work,  and  drawing  Out  of  Work  pay  from 
the  funds.  To  let  these  take  the  places  left  vacant — to 
"  blackleg  "  the  rival  society — is  to  commit  the  gravest  crime 
against  the  Trade  Unionist  faith.  Unfortunately,  in  many 
cases,  the  temptation  is  irresistible.  The  friction  between 
the  rival  organisations,  the  personal  ill-feeling  of  their  officers, 
the  traditions  of  past  grievances,  the  temptation  of  pecuniary 
gain  both  to  the  workmen  and  to  the  union,  all  co-operate  to 
make  the  occasion  "  an  exception."  At  this  stage  any  pretext 
suffices.  The  unreasonableness  of  the  other  society's  demand, 
the  fact  that  it  did  not  consult  its  rival  before  taking  action, 
even  the  non-arrival  of  the  letter  officially  announcing  the 
strike,  serves  as  a  plausible  excuse  in  the  subsequent  recrimi- 
nations. Scarcely  a  year  passes  without  the  Trade  Union 
Congress  being  made  the  scene  of  a  heated  accusation  by  one 
society  or  another,  that  some  other  union  has  "  blacklegged  " 
a  dispute  in  which  it  was  engaged,  and  thereby  deprived  its 
members  of  all  the  results  of  their  combination.1 

1  Whenever  rivalry  and  competition  for  members  have  existed  between  unions 
in  the  same  industry  we  find  numberless  cases  of  "  blacklegging."  The  relations, 
for  instance,  between  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers,  and  all  the  sectional 
societies,  abound  in  unfortunate  instances  on  the  one  side  or  the  other.  The  two 
societies  of  Bricklayers  have,  in  the  past,  frequently  accused  each  other's  members 
of  the  same  crime.  The  "excursions  across  the  Border"  of  the  English  and 
Scottish  societies  of  Tailors  and  Plumbers  have  been  enlivened  by  similar  recrimi- 
nations, which  are  also  bandied  about  among  the  several  unions  of  general 
laborers.  The  Coalmining  and  Cotton  manufacturing  industries  are  honorably 
free  from  this  feature.  An  exceptionally  bad  case  of  an  established  union  becoming, 
through  blacklegging,  a  mere  tool  of  the  employers,  came  to  light  at  the  Trade 
Union  Congress  of  1892,  and  was  personally  investigated  by  us. 

The  Glasgow  Harbour  Laborers'  Union,  established  among  the  Clyde  steve- 
dores in  1853,  had,  up  to  1889,  maintained  an  honorable  record  for  stability  and 
success.  In  the  latter  year  it  found  itself,  with  only  230  members,  menaced  with 
extinction  by  the  sudden  uprising  of  the  National  Union  of  Dock  Laborers  in 
Great  Britain  and  Ireland,  a  society  organised  on  the  antagonistic  idea  of  including 
every  kind  of  dock  and  wharf  laborers  in  a  national  amalgamation.  The  small, 


Interunion  Relations  1 2 1 

The  foregoing  detailed  description  has  placed  the  reader 
in  a  position  to  appreciate  the  disastrous  effect  of  com- 
petition between  Trade  Unions  for  members.  Whilst 
seriously  impairing  their  financial  stability  as  benefit  clubs, 
this  rivalry  cuts  at  the  root  of  all  effective  trade  combination. 
It  is  no  exaggeration  to  say  that  to  competition  between 
overlapping  unions  is  to  be  attributed  nine- tenths  of  the 
ineffectiveness  of  the  Trade  Union  world.  The  great  army 
of  engineering  operatives,  for  instance,  though  exceptional  in 
training  and  intelligence,  and  enrolled  in  stable  and  well- 
administered  societies,  have  as  yet  not  succeeded  either  in 
negotiating  with  the  employers  on  anything  like  equal  terms, 
or  in  maintaining  among  themselves  any  common  policy 
whatsoever.  An  even  larger  section  of  the  wage -earning 
world — that  engaged  in  the  great  industry  of  transport — has 
so  far  failed,  from  a  similar  cause,  to  build  up  any  really 
effective  Trade  Unionism.  The  millions  of  laborers,  who 

old-fashioned,  and  local  society,  with  its  traditions  of  exclusiveness  and  "privilege," 
refused  to  merge  itself,  but  offered  to  its  big  rival  a  mutual  "  next  preference  " 
working  arrangement — that  is  to  say,  whilst  each  society  maintained  for  its  own 
members  a  preferential  right  to  be  taken  on  at  the  wharves  or  yards  where  they 
were  accustomed  to  work,  it  should  accord  to  the  members  of  the  other  society 
the  right  to  fill  any  further  vacancies  at  those  yards  or  wharves  in  preference  to 
outsiders.  The  answer  to  this  was  a  peremptory  refusal  on  the  part  of  the 
National  Union  to  recognise  the  existence  of  its  tiny  predecessor,  whose  members 
accordingly  found  themselves  absolutely  excluded  from  work.  The  National 
Union  no  doubt  calculated  that  it  would,  in  this  way,  compel  the  smaller  society 
to  yield.  But  at  the  very  moment  it  had  a  great  struggle  on  hand,  both  in  Liver- 
pool and  Glasgow,  with  one  of  the  principal  shipping  firms.  Communications 
were  quickly  opened  up  between  that  firm  and  the  Glasgow  Harbour  Laborers', 
Society,  with  the  result  that  the  latter  undertook  to  do  the  firm's  work,  and  thus 
at  one  blow  not  only  defeated  the  aggressive  pretensions  of  the  National  Union 
but  also  secured  its  own  existence.  This  line  of  conduct  was  repeated  whenever 
a  dispute  arose  between  the  employers  and  any  Union  on  the  Clyde.  When  the 
Hlast-furnacemen  on  strike  had  successfully  appealed  to  the  National  Amalgamated 
Sailors'  and  Firemen's  Union,  not  to  unload  Spanish  pig  iron,  the  Glasgow  Harboui 
Laborers'  Union  promptly  came  to  the  employers'  rescue.  During  the  strike  of 
the  Scottish  Railway  Servants'  Union,  the  same  society  was  to  the  fore  in  supplying 
"scab  laborers."  Its  crowning  degradation,  in  Trade  Union  eyes,  came  in  an 
alliance  with  the  Shipping  Federation,  the  powerful  combination  by  which  the 
employers  have,  since  1892,  sought  to  crush  the  whole  Trade  Union  movement 
in  the  waterside  industries.  Its  conduct  was,  in  that  year,  brought  before  the 
Trade  Union  Congress,  which  happened  to  meet  at  Glasgow,  and  the  Congress 
almost  unanimously  voted  the  exclusion  of  its  delegates. 


i  2  2  Trade  Union  Structure 

must  in  any  case  find  it  difficult  to  maintain  a  common 
organisation,  are  constantly  hampered  in  their  progress  by 
the  existence  of  competing  societies  which,  starting  from 
different  industries,  quickly  pass  into  general  unions,  in- 
cluding each  other's  members.  Indeed,  with  the  remarkable 
exceptions  of  the  coal  and  cotton  industries,  and,  to  a 
lesser  extent,  that  of  house-building,  there  is  hardly  a  great 
trade  in  the  country  in  which  the  workmen's  organisations 
are  not  seriously  crippled  by  this  fatal  dissension. 

Now,  experience  shows  that  the  permanent  cause  of  this 
competitive  rivalry  and  overlapping  between  unions  is  their 
organisation  upon  bases  inconsistent  with  each  other.  When 
two  societies  include  and  exclude  precisely  the  same  sections 
of  workmen,  competition  between  them  loses  half  its  bitter- 
ness, and  the  solution  of  the  difficulty  is  only  a  question  of 
time.  We  see,  for  instance*  since  1862,  the  Amalgamated 
Society  of  Carpenters  and  Joiners  rapidly  distancing  its  elder 
competitor,  the  General  Union  of  Carpenters  and  Joiners 
(established  1827).  But  because  the  members  of  both 
societies  belong  to  identically  the  same  trade,  are  paid  by 
the  same  methods,  earn  the  same  rates,  work  the  same  hours, 
have  the  same  customs  and  needs,  and  are  in  no  way  to 
be  distinguished  from  each  other,  the  branches  in  a  given 
town  find  no  difficulty  in  concerting,  by  means  of  a  joint 
committee,  a  common  trade  policy.  And  although  the 
existence  of  two  societies  weakens  the  financial  position  of 
the  one  as  well  as  of  the  other,  the  identity  of  the  members' 
income  and  requirements,  and  their  constant  intercourse,  tend 
steadily  to  an  approximation  of  the  respective  scales  of 
contribution  and  benefits.  Under  these  circumstances  the 
tendency  to  amalgamation  is,  as  we  have  seen  in  the  pre- 
ceding chapter,  almost  irresistible,  and  is  usually  delayed 
only  by  the  natural  reluctance  of  some  particular  official  to 
abdicate  the  position  of  leadership. 

The  problem  which  the  engineers,  the  transit  workers, 
and  the  laborers  have  so  far  failed  to  solve,  is  how  to 
define  a  trade.  Among  the  engineers,  for  instance,  there  is 


Interunion  Relations  123 

no  general  agreement  which  groups  of  workmen  have 
interests  sufficiently  distinct  from  the  remainder  as  to  make 
it  necessary  for  them  to  combine  in  a  sectional  organisation  ; 
and  there  is  but  little  proper  appreciation  of  the  relation 
of  these  sectional  interests  to  those  which  all  engineering 
mechanics  have  in  common.  The  enthusiast  for  amalgama- 
tion is  always  harping  on  the  necessity  of  union  amongst 
all  classes  of  engineering  workmen  in  order  to  abolish 
systematic  overtime,  to  reduce  the  normal  hours  of  labor, 
and  to  obtain  recognition  of  Trade  Union  conditions  from 
the  government.  To  the  member  of  the  United  Pattern- 
makers' Association  or  of  the  Associated  Blacksmiths, 
these  objects,  however  desirable,  are  subordinate  to  some 
re  -  arrangement  of  the  method  or  scale  of  remuneration 
peculiar  to  his  own  occupation.  The  solution  of  the 
problem  is  to  be  found  in  a  form  of  organisation  which 
secures  Home  Rule  for  any  group  possessing  interests 
divergent  from  those  of  the  industry  as  a  whole,  whilst 
at  the  same  time  maintaining  effective  combination  through- 
out the  entire  industry  for  the  promotion  of  the  interests 
which  are  common  to  all  the  sections. 

Fortunately,  we  are  not  left  to  our  imagination  to  devise 
a  paper  constitution  which  would  fulfil  these  conditions.  In 
another  industry  we  find  the  problem  solved  with  almost 
perfect  success.  We  have  already  described  the  half- 
dozen  distinct  classes  into  which  the  Cotton  Operatives  are 
naturally  divided.  Each  of  these  has  its  own  independent 
union,  which  carries  on  its  own  negotiations  with  the 
employers,  and  would  vigorously  resist  any  proposal  for 
amalgamation.  But  in  addition  to  the  sectional  interests 
of  each  of  the  six  classes,  there  are  subjects  upon  which  two 
or  more  of  the  sections  feel  in  common,  and  others  which 
concern  them  all.  Accordingly,  instead  of  amalgamation 
on  the  one  hand,  or  isolation  on  the  other,  we  find  the 
sectional  unions  combining  with  each  other  in  various 
federal  organisations  of  great  efficiency.  The  Cotton- 
spinners  and  the  Cardroom  Operatives,  working  always  for 


124  Trade  Union  Structure 

the  same  employers  in  the  same  establishments,  have 
formed  the  Cotton -Workers'  Association,  to  the  funds  of 
which  both  societies  contribute.  Each  constituent  union 
carried  on  its  own  collective  bargaining  and  has  its  own 
funds.  But  it  agrees  to  call  out  its  members  in  support 
of  the  other's  dispute,  whenever  requested  to  do  so,  the 
members  so  withdrawn  being  supported  from  the  federal 
fund.  The  Cotton-spinners  thus  secure  the  stoppage  of 
the  material  for  their  work,  whenever  they  withdraw  their 
labor,  and  thereby  place  an  additional  obstacle  in  the  way 
of  the  employer  obtaining  blackleg  spinners.  The  Card- 
room  Operatives  on  the  other  hand,  whose  labor  is  almost 
unskilled,  and  could  easily  be  replaced,  obtain  in  their 
disputes  the  advantage  of  the  support  of  the  indispensable 
Cotton-spinners.  No  federation  for  these  purposes  would  be 
of  use  to  the  Cotton -weavers,  who  often  work  for  employers 
devoting  themselves  exclusively  to  weaving,  and  whose 
product  goes  to  a  different  market.  But  the  Cotton-weavers 
join  with  the  Cotton-spinners  and  the  Cardroom  Operatives 
in  the  United  Textile  Factory  Workers'  Association,  a  purely 
political  organisation  for  the  purpose  of  obtaining  and  en- 
forcing the  factory  and  other  legislation  common  to  the 
whole  trade.1  And  it  is  interesting  to  notice  that  the 
Cotton  Operatives  not  only  refrain  from  converting  this 
strong  and  stable  federation  into  an  amalgamation,  but  even 
carry  the  federal  form  into  the  different  sections  of  their 
industry.  The  19,000  Cotton-spinners,  for  instance,  form 
a  single  righting  unit,  which,  for  compactness  and  absolute 
discipline,  bears  comparison  even  with  the  United  Society 
of  Boilermakers.  But  though  the  Cotton-spinners  call  their 
union  an  amalgamation,  the  larger  "  provinces  "  retain  the 
privilege  of  electing  their  own  officers,  and  of  fixing  their 
own  contributions  for  local  purposes  and  special  benefits, 
and  even  preserve  a  certain  degree  of  legislative  autonomy. 
The  student  who  derives  his  impression  of  these  organisa- 
tions merely  from  their  elaborate  separate  rules  and  reports, 

1  This  organisation  was  temporarily  suspended  in  1896. 


Interunion  Relations.  125 

might  easily  conclude  that,  in  the  relation  between  the 
Oldham  or  Bolton  "  province,"  and  the  "  Representative 
Meeting"  of  the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative 
Cotton-spinners,  we  have  a  genuine  case  of  local  and  central 
government.  This,  however,  is  not  the  case.  The  partial 
autonomy  of  the  "  provinces  "  of  Oldham  and  Bolton  is  not 
a  case  of  geographical,  but  of  industrial  specialisation. 
Each  "  province "  has  its  own  peculiar  trade,  spinning 
different  "counts"  for  widely  different  markets.  Each  is 
governed  by  its  own  peculiar  list  of  piecework  prices,  based 
on  different  considerations.  And  though  the  prevailing 
tendency  is  towards  a  greater  uniformity  of  terms  and 
methods,  there  is  still  a  sufficient  distinction  between  the 
Oldham  and  Bolton  trades  themselves,  and  between  those 
of  the  smaller  districts,  to  make  any  amalgamation  a 
hazardous  experiment.  Similar  considerations  have  hitherto 
applied  to  the  Cotton  -  weavers,  who  have,  indeed,  only 
recently  united  into  a  single  body.  Differences  of  trade 
interests,  not  easy  of  explanation  to  the  outsider,  have 
hitherto  separated  town  and  town,  each  working  under  its 
own  piecework  list.  These  sectional  differences  resulted, 
until  lately,  in  organisation  by  loosely  federated  autonomous 
groups.  It  is  at  least  an  interesting  coincidence  that  the 
increasing  uniformity  of  conditions  which,  in  1884,  per- 
mitted the  concentration  of  these  groups  into  the  Northern 
Counties  Amalgamated  Association  of  Cotton-weavers,  re- 
sulted, in  1892,  in  the  adoption,  from  one  end  of  Lancashire  . 
to  the  other,  of  a  uniform  piecework  list. 

The  history  of  Trade  Unionism  among  the  Coalminers 
also  supplies  instructive  instances  of  federal  action. 
In  Northumberland  and  Durham  the  present  unions 
included,  for  the  first  ten  years  of  their  existence,  not 
only  the  actual  hewers  of  the  coal,  but  also  the  Deputies 
(Overlookers),  the  Enginemen,  the  Cokemen,  and  the 
Mechanics  employed  in  connection  with  the  collieries.  This 
is  still  the  type  of  union  in  some  of  the  more  recently 
organised  districts.  Both  in  Northumberland  and  in 


126  Trade  Union  Structure 

Durham,  however,  experience  of  the  difficulties  of  com- 
bining such  diverse  workers  has  led  to  the  formation  of 
distinct  unions  for  Deputies,  Cokemen,  and  Colliery 
Mechanics.  Each  of  these  acts  with  complete  independ- 
ence in  dealing  with  the  special  circumstances  of  its  own 
occupation,  but  unites  with  the  others  in  the  same  county 
in  a  strong  federation  for  general  wage  movements.1  And 
if  we  pass  from  the  "  county  federations "  which  are  so 
characteristic  of  this  industry,  to  the  attempts  to  weld  all 
coal-hewers  into  a  single  national  organisation,  we  shall  see 
that  these  attempts  have  hitherto  succeeded  only  when  they 
have  taken  the  federal  form.  In  1868  and  again  in  1874 
attempts  at  complete  amalgamation  quickly  came  to  grief. 
Effective  federation  of  all  the  organised  districts  has,  on  the 
other  hand,  endured  since  i863.2  We  attribute  this  pre- 
ference for  the  federal  form,  not  to  the  difficulty  of  uniting 
the  geographically  separated  coalfields,  but  to  the  divergence 
of  interests  between  them.  Northumberland,  Durham,  and 
South  Wales,  producing  chiefly  for  foreign  export,  feel 
that  their  trade  has  little  in  common  with  that  of  the 
Midland  Coalfields,  which  supply  the  home  market.  The 
thin  seams  of  Somersetshire  demand  different  methods  of 
working,  different  rates  of  remuneration,  and  different 
allowances,  from  those  in  vogue  in  the  rich  mines  of  York- 
shire. The  "  fiery  "  mines  of  Monmouthshire  demand  quite 
a  different  set  of  working  rules  from  the  harmless  seams  of 
Cannock  Chase.3  It  was,  therefore,  quite  natural  that,  in 
1887,  when  a  demand  arose  for  a  strong  and  active  national 
organisation,  this  did  not  take  the  form  of  an  amalgamated 
union.  The  Miners'  Federation,  which  now  includes  200,000 
members  from  Fife  to  Somerset,  is  composed  of  separate 

1  The  Durham  County  Mining  Federation,  established   1878,  includes  the 
Durham  Coalminers,    Enginemen's,    Cokemen's,    and   Mechanics'   Associations. 
The  Northumberland  associations  have  not  established  any  formal  federation  but 
act  constantly  together. 

2  See  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  274,  287,  335,  350,  380. 

3  See,  for  instance,  the  animated  discussion  on  proposed  clause  to  restrict 
shot-firing,  National  Conference  of  Miners,  Birmingham,  9th-i2th  January  1893. 


Inter  union  Relations  \  2  7 

unions,  each  retaining  complete  autonomy  in  its  own  affairs, 
and  only  asking  for  the  help  of  the  federal  body  in  matters 
common  to  the  whole  kingdom,  or  in  case  of  a  local  dispute 
extending  to  over  1 5  per  cent  of  the  members.  Any 
attempt  to  draw  tighter  these  bonds  of  union  would,  in  all 
probability,  at  once  cause  the  secession  of  the  Scottish 
Miners'  unions,  and  would  absolutely  preclude  the  adhesion 
of  Northumberland,  Durham,  and  South  Wales.1 

1  Other  industries  afford  instances  of  federal  union.  The  compositors  employed 
in  the  offices  of  the  great  London  daily  newspapers,  at  specially  high  wages,  and 
under  quite  exceptional  conditions,  have,  since  1853,  formed  an  integral  part  of 
the  London  Society  of  Compositors.  But  they  have,  from  the  beginning,  had 
their  own  quarterly  meetings,  and  elected  their  own  separate  executive  committee 
and  salaried  secretary,  who  conduct  all  their  distinctive  trade  business,  moving 
for  new  privileges  and  advances  independently  of  the  general  body.  One  or 
more  delegates  are  appointed  by  the  News  Department  to  represent  it  at  general 
or  delegate  meetings  of  the  whole  society,  whilst  two  representatives  of  the  Book 
Department  (which  comprises  nine-tenths  of  the  society)  sit  on  the  newsmen's 
executive  committee.  There  is  even  a  tendency  to  establish  similar  relations 
with  the  special  "  music  printers."  The  National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe 
Operatives  presents  an  example  of  incipient  federation.  The  union  is  made  up 
of  large  branches  in  the  several  towns,  each  possessing  local  funds  and  appointing 
its  own  salaried  officials.  In  so  far  as  the  members  belong  to  an  identical 
occupation,  the  tendency  is  towards  increased  centralisation.  But  it  has  become 
the  rule  for  the  members  in  each  town  to  divide  into  branches,  not  according 
to  geographical  propinquity,  but  according  to  the  class  of  work  which  they  do. 
Thus,  in  any  town,  "  No.  I  Branch  "  is  composed  exclusively  of  Rivetters  and 
Finishers,  "No.  2  Branch"  are  the  Clickers,  and  where  a  separate  class  of 
Jewish  workers  exists,  these  form  a  "No.  3  Branch."  The  central  executive 
is  elected  by  electoral  divisions  according  to  membership,  and  has  hitherto 
usually  been  composed  exclusively  of  the  predominating  classes  of  Rivetters  and 
Finishers.  But  the  Clickers,  whose  interests  diverge  from  those  of  their 
colleagues,  have,  for  some  time,  been  demanding  separate  representation,  which 
they  have  now  been  informally  granted  by  the  election  of  their  chief  salaried 
official  as  treasurer  of  the  whole  union.  A  similar  movement  may  be  discerned 
among  the  Finishers,  as  against  the  Rivetters  (now  become  "Lasters"),  and  it 
seems  probable  that  this  desire  for  sectional  representation,  following  on  partial 
sectional  autonomy,  will  presently  find  formal  recognition  in  the  constitution. 

The  building  trades  afford  an  interesting  case  of  the  abandonment  of  the 
experiment  of  a  general  union  in  favor  of  separate  national  societies,  which  are 
not  at  present  united  in  any  national  federation.  The  Builders'  Union  of  1830-34 
aimed  at  the  ideal  afterwards  pursued  in  the  engineering  industry.  All  the 
operatives  engaged  in  the  seven  sections  of  the  building  trade  were  to  be  united 
in  a  single  national  amalgamation.  This  attempt  has  never  been  repeated.  ^  In 
its  place  we  have  the  great  national  unions  of  Stonemasons,  Carpenters,  Brick- 
layers, Plumbers,  and  Plasterers,  whilst  the  Painters  and  the  Builders'  Laborers 
have  not  yet  emerged  from  the  stage  of  the  local  trade  club.  Between  the 
central  executives  of  these  societies  there  is  no  federal  union.  In  almost  every 


128  Trade  Union  Structitre 

These  examples  of  success  and  failure  in  uniting  several 
sections  of  workmen  in  a  single  unit  of  government,  point 
to  the  existence  of  an  upper  and  a  lower  limit  to  the 
process  of  amalgamation.  It  is  one  of  the  conditions  of 
effective  trade  action  that  a  union  should  include  all  the 
workmen  whose  occupation  or  training  is  such  as  to  enable 
them,  at  short  notice,  to  fill  the  places  held  by  its  members. 
It  would,  for  instance,  be  most  undesirable  for  such  inter- 
changeable mechanics  as  fitters,  turners,  and  erectors,  to 
maintain  separate  Trade  Unions,  with  distinct  trade  policies. 
And  if  the  Cardroom  Operatives  could  easily  "  mind  "  the 
self-acting  mule  of  the  Cotton-spinners,  it  might  possibly 
suit  the  latter  to  arrange  an  amalgamation  between  the  two 
societies,  just  as  the  Rivetters  found  it  convenient  to  absorb 
the  Holders-up  into  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers  and 
Iron  Shipbuilders.1  There  appears  to  be  no  advantage  in 
carrying  amalgamation  (as  distinct  from  federation)  beyond 
this  point.  But  there  are  often  serious  difficulties  in  going 
even  thus  far.  The  efficient  working  of  an  amalgamated 
society  requires  that  all  sections  of  the  members  should  be 
fairly  uniform  in  the  methods  of  their  remuneration,  the 
conditions  of  their  employment,  and  the  amount  of  their 
standard  earnings.  Moreover,  it  may  confidently  be  pre- 
dicted that  no  amalgamation  will  be  stable  in  which  the 
several  sections  differ  appreciably  in  strategic  position,  in 
such  a  manner  as  to  make  it  advantageous  for  them  to 

town  there  has,  however,  grown  up  a  local  Building  Trades'  Federation,  formed 
by  the  local  branches  to  concert  joint  action  against  their  common  employers, 
as  regards  hours  of  labor  and  local  advances  or  reductions  of  wages,  both  of 
which  are  in  each  town  usually  simultaneous  and  identical  for  all  sections.  We 
have  elsewhere  referred  to  the  difficulties  arising  from  this  separate  action  of  each 
town,  and  it  is  at  least  open  to  argument  whether  the  building  trades  would  not 
be  better  advised  to  form  a  national  federation  to  concert  a  common  national 
policy,  having  federal  officials  in  the  large  towns,  who  would,  like  the  district 
delegates  of  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  represent  the  whole  organisation, 
though  acting  in  consultation  with  local  committees. 

1  The  Holders-up  were  admitted  into  the  society  in  1881,  at  the  instance  of 
the  general  secretary,  who  represented  that  Holders-up  were  indispensable  fellow  - 
workers  and  possible  blacklegs,  and  must  therefore  be  brought  under  the  control 
of  the  organisation,  more  especially  as  they  were  beginning  to  form  separate  clubs 
of  their  own. 


InierUnion  Relations  129 

move  at  different  times,  or  by  different  expedients. 
Finally,  experience  seems  to  show  that  in  no  trade  will  a 
well-paid  and  well-organised  but  numerically  weak  section 
permanently  consent  to  remain  in  the  subordination  to 
inferior  operatives,  which  any  amalgamation  of  all  sections 
of  a  large  and  varied  industry  must  usually  involve. 

Let  us  apply  these  axioms  to  the  tangle  of  competing 
societies  in  the  engineering  trade.  The  fitters,  turners, 
and  erectors  who  work  in  the  same  shop,  on  the  same  job, 
under  identical  methods  of  remuneration,  for  wages  ap- 
proximately equal  in  amount,  and  who  can  without  difficulty 
do  each  other's  work,  form,  no  doubt,  a  natural  unit  of 
government.1  We  might  perhaps  add  to  these  the  smiths, 
though  the  persistence  of  a  few  separate  smiths'  societies, 
and  the  uprising  of  joint  societies  of  smiths  and  strikers, 
may  indicate  a  different  cleavage.  With  regard  to  the 
pattern-makers,  it  is  easy  to  understand  why  the  United 
Pattern-makers'  Association  is  now  attracting  a  majority  of 
the  men  entering  this  section  of  the  trade.  These  highly 
skilled  and  superior  artisans  constitute  a  tiny  minority  amid 
the  great  engineering  army  ;  they  usually  enjoy  a  higher 
Standard  Rate  than  any  other  section  ;  and  any  advances 
or  reductions  in  their  wages  must  almost  necessarily  occur 
at  different  times  from  similar  changes  among  the  engineers 
proper.  It  is  even  open  to  argument  whether,  for  Collective 
Bargaining,  the  pattern-makers  are  not  actually  stronger  when 
acting  alone  than  when  in  alliance  with  the  whole  engineering, 
industry.  We  are,  therefore,  disposed  to  agree  with  the  con- 
tention of  the  United  Pattern-makers'  Association  that  "when 
the  interests  of  our  own  particular  section  are  concerned,  we 
hold  it  as  the  first  principle  of  our  Association  that  these 
interests  can  only  be  thoroughly  understood,  and  effectively 
looked  after,  by  ourselves."2  The  same  conclusions  apply, 

1  In  1896,  though  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  enrolled  the  un- 
precedented total  of  13,321  new  members,  all  but  1803  of  these  belonged  to  the 
classes  of  fitters,  turners,  or  millwrights. 

2  Preface  to  Rules  of  the  United  Pattern-makers'  Association   (Manchester, 
1892). 

VOL.  I  K 


1 3o 


Trade  Union  Structure 


though  in  a  lesser  degree,  to  some  other  sections  now  included 
in  the  Amalgamated  Society,  and  they  would  decisively 
negative  the  suggestion  to  absorb  such  distinct  and  highly 
organised  trades  as  the  Plumbers  and  Ironfounders.1 

This  conclusion  does  not  mean  that  each  section  of  the 
engineering  trade  should  maintain  a  complete  independence. 
"  We  quite  acknowledge,"  state  the  Pattern-makers,  "  that 
it  would  be  neither  politic  nor  possible  to  completely  sever 
our  connection  with  the  organisation  representative  of  the 
engineering  trade,  and  we  are  always  ready  to  co-operate 
with  contemporary  societies  in  movements  which  affect  the 
interests  of  the  general  body." 2  There  are,  indeed,  some 
matters  as  to  which  the  whole  engineering  industry  must  act 
in  concert  if  it  is  to  act  at  all.  A  great  establishment  like 
Elswick,  employing  10,000  operatives  in  every  section  of 
the  industry,  would  find  it  intolerable  to  conduct  separate 
negotiations,  and  fix  different  meal-times  or  different  holidays 
for  the  different  branches  of  the  trade.  We  find,  in  fact,  the 
associated  employers  on  the  North-east  Coast  expressly  com- 

1  Our  analysis  thus  definitely  refutes  the  suggestion  that  the  quarrels  be- 
tween the  engineers  and  plumbers,  and  the  shipwrights  and  joiners  respectively, 
might  be  obviated  by  the  amalgamation  of  the  competing  unions.  The  two 
trades  overlap  in  a  few  shipbuilding  jobs,  but  in  nine-tenths  of  their  work  it 
would  be  impossible  for  an  engineer  to  take  the  place  of  the  plumber,  or  a  ship- 
wright that  of  a  joiner,  or  vice  versd.  In  strategic  position  the  plumber  differs 
fundamentally  from  the  engineer,  and  the  joiner  from  the  shipwright.  The 
engineering  and  shipbuilding  trades  are  subject  to  violent  fluctuations,  which 
depend  upon  the  alternate  inflations  and  depressions  of  the  national  commerce. 
The  building  trades,  on  the  other  hand,  with  which  nine-tenths  of  the  joiners  and 
plumbers  must  be  counted,  vary  considerably  according  to  the  season  of  the  year, 
but  fluctuate  comparatively  little  from  year  to  year  ;  and  the  general  fluctuations 
to  which  they  are  subject  do  not  coincide  with  those  of  the  shipbuilding  and 
engineering  industries.  By  the  time  that  the  wave  of  expansion  has  reached  the 
building  trades,  the  staple  industries  of  the  country  are  already  in  the  trough  of 
the  succeeding  depression.  It  would  have  been  difficult  to  have  persuaded  a 
Newcastle  engineer  or  a  shipwright  in  the  spring  of  1893,  when  20  per  cent  of 
his  colleagues  were  out  of  work,  that  the  plumbers  and  carpenters  were  well 
advised  in  choosing  that  particular  moment  to  press  for  better  terms.  Finally,  we 
have  the  almost  insuperable  difficulty  of  securing  adequate  representation  for  the 
9000  plumbers,  scattered  in  every  town  amid  the  87,000  engineers  ;  and,  on  the 
other  hand,  the  14,000  shipwrights  concentrated  in  a  few  ports  amid  the  49,000 
joiners  spread  over  the  whole  country. 

2  Preface  to  Rules  of  the  United  Pattern-makers'  Association  (Manchester, 
1892). 


Interunion  Relations  131 

plaining  in  1890,  "  of  the  great  inconvenience  and  difficulty 
experienced  in  the  settlement  of  wages  and  other  general 
questions  between  employers  and  employed";  and  ascribing 
the  constant  friction  that  prevailed  to  the  "  want  of  uniformity 
of  action  and  similarity  of  demand  put  forward  by  the 
various  societies  representing  the  skilled  engineering  labor." 
Collective  Bargaining  becomes  impracticable  when  different 
societies  are  proposing  new  regulations  on  overtime  in- 
consistent with  each  other,  and  when  rival  organisations, 
each  claiming  to  represent  the  same  section  of  the  trade,  are 
putting  forward  divergent  claims  as  to  the  methods  and 
rates  of  remuneration.  The  employers  were  driven  to  insist 
that  the  "  deputations  meeting  them  to  negotiate  .  .  .  should 
represent  all  the  societies  interested  in  the  question  under 
consideration." *  And  when  the  method  to  be  employed  is 
not  Collective  Bargaining  but  Parliamentary  action,  federal 
union  is  even  more  necessary.  If  the  mechanics  in  the 
great  government  arsenals  and  factories  desire  modifica- 
tions in  their  conditions  of  employment,  union  of  purpose 
among  the  tens  of  thousands  of  engineering  electors  all  over 
the  country  is  indispensable  for  success. 

So  long,  however,  as  the  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Engineers  claims  to  include  within  its  own  ranks  every 
kind  of  engineering  mechanic,  and  to  decide  by  itself  the 
policy  to  be  pursued,  a  permanent  and  effective  federal 
organisation  is  impossible.  Any  attempt  to  combine  in  the 
same  industry  the  mutually  inconsistent  schemes  of  amal- 
gamation and  federation  may  even  intensify  the  friction. 
Thus  we  find,  in  1888,  to  quote  again  from  a  report  of  the 

1  Circular  of  the  Iron  Trades  Employers'  Association  on  the  Overtime  Ques- 
tion, October  1891.  We  attribute  the  practical  failure  of  the  Engineering 
operatives  to  check  systematic  overtime,  an  evil  against  which  they  have  been 
striving  ever  since  1836,  to  the  chaotic  state  of  the  organisation  of  the  trade.  A 
similar  lack  of  federal  union  stood  in  the  way  of  the  London  bookbinders  in  1893, 
when  they  succeeded  without  great  difficulty  in  obtaining  an  Eight  Hours'  Day 
from  those  employers  who  were  bookbinders  only.  In  the  great  printing  estab- 
lishments, such  as  Waterlow's  and  Spottiswoode's,  they  found  it  practically 
impossible  to  arrange  an  Eight  Hours'  Day  in  the  binding  departments,  whilst 
the  printers  continued  to  work  for  longer  hours. 


132  Trade  Union  Structure 

United  Pattern-makers'  Association,  "the  sectional  societies 
(on  North-east  Coast),  indignant  at  the  arbitrary  manner  in 
which  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  had  acted, 
federated  together  with  the  avowed  object  of  resisting  a 
repetition  of  any  such  behaviour  in  case  of  further  wages 
movements,  and  asserting  their  right  to  be  consulted  before 
definite  action  was  taken.  ...  It  is  impossible,"  continues 
the  report,  "  to  dissociate  the  action  of  our  contemporaries 
(the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers)  from  their  recent 
unsuccessful  attempt  at  amalgamating  the  various  sectional 
societies ;  and  it  would  seem  that  they,  rinding  it  impossible 
to  absorb  their  weaker  brethren  by  fair  means,  had  resolved 
to  shatter  the  confidence  they  have  in  their  unions  by 
showing  them  their  impotence  to  influence,  of  themselves, 
their  relations  between  their  employers  and  members."  l  The 
"  Federal  Board,"  thus  formed  by  the  smaller  engineering 
societies  on  Tyneside  in  antagonism  to  their  more  powerful 
rival,  lasted  for  three  years,  but  failed,  it  is  needless  to  say, 
in  securing  industrial  peace.  A  more  important  and  more 
promising  attempt  has  been  marred  by  the  persistent  absten- 
tion of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers.  In  1890, 
Mr.  Robert  Knight,  the  able  general  secretary  of  the  United 
Society  of  Boilermakers,  succeeded,  after  repeated  failures,  in 
drawing  together  in  a  powerful  national  federation  the  great 
majority  of  the  unions  connected  with  the  engineering  and 
shipbuilding  industries.  This  "  Federation  of  Engineering  and 
Shipbuilding  Trades  of  the  United  Kingdom  "  includes  such 
powerful  organisations  as  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers, 
40,776  members ;  the  Associated  Shipwrights'  Society,  1 4,2  3  5 
members  ;  and  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Carpenters  and 
Joiners,  48,631  members,  who  are  content  to  meet  on  equal 
terms  such  smaller  unions  as  the  Steam-Engine  Makers' 
Society,  7000  members  ;  the  United  Operative  Plumbers' 
Society,  8758  members;  the  United  Pattern-makers'  Associa- 
tion, 3636  members;  the  National  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Painters  and  Decorators,  and  half  a  dozen  more  minute 

1  Monthly  Report  of  the  United  Pattern-makers'  Society,  January  1889. 


Interunion  Relations  133 


sectional  societies.  This  federation  has  now  lasted  over  seven 
years,  and  has  fulfilled  a  useful  function  in  settling  disputes 
between  the  different  unions.  But  as  an  instrument  for 
Collective  Bargaining  with  the  employers,  or  for  taking 
concerted  action  on  behalf  of  the  whole  industry,  it  is  useless 
so  long  as  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers,  with  its 
87,455  members,  holds  resolutely  aloof.  And  the  Amal- 
gamated Society  of  Engineers,  still  wedded  to  the  ideal  of 
one  undivided  union,  cannot  bring  itself  to  accept  as  per- 
manent colleagues,  the  sectional  societies  which  it  regards 
as  illegitimate  combinations  undermining  its  own  position.1 

1  The  first  numbers  of  the  Amalgamated  Engineers'  Monthly  Journal — an 
official  organ  started  on  the  accession  of  Mr.  George  Barnes  to  the  general 
secretaryship — shows  that  thinking  members  of  the  Amalgamation  are  coming 
round  to  the  idea  of  federal  union  with  the  sectional  societies,  and  others  con- 
nected with  the  engineering  and  shipbuilding  industry.  Thus  Mr.  Tom  Mann,  in 
the  opening  number  (January  1897,  pp.  10-11),  declares  "that  the  bulk  of  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers'  men  are  ashamed  ...  of  their  present  power- 
lessness.  .  .  .  Whence  comes  the  weakness  ?  Beyond  any  doubt  it  is  primarily  due 
to  the  fact  that  no  concerted  action  is  taken  by  the  various  unions.  .  .  .  That  is, 
the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  has  not  yet  learnt  the  necessity  for  form- 
ing part  of  a  real  federation  of  all  trades  connected  with  this  particular  profession. 
.  .  .  What  member  can  look  back  over  the  last  few  years  and  not  blush  with  shame 
at  what  has  taken  place  between  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  and  the 
Plumbers,  and  the  Boilermakers  and  Shipbuilders  ;  and  who  can  derive  satisfac- 
tion in  reflecting  upon  the  want  of  friendly  relations  between  the  Amalgamated 
Society  of  Engineers  .  .  .  and  the  Pattern-makers  and  Shipwrights,  and  Steam  - 
Engine  Makers,  etc.  ?  A  fighting  force  is  wanted  .  .  .  and  this  can  only  be 
obtained  by  a  genuine  federation  of  societies  connected  with  the  trades  referred 
to.  ...  The  textile  workers  (cotton)  have  federated  the  various  societies,  and 
are  able  to  secure  united  action  on  a  scale  distinctly  in  advance  of  that  of  the 
engineering  trades."  And  in  the  succeeding  issue  Mr.  John  Burns  vigorously 
strikes  the  same  note.  "  To  really  prevent  this  internecine  and  disintegrating 
strife,  the  first  step  for  the  Amalgamated  Engineers  this  year  is  to  join  at  once 
with  all  the  other  unions  in  [a]  federation  of  engineering  trades."  Two  months 
later  (April  1897,  pp.  12-14)  comes  a  furious  denunciation  of  the  proposal, 
signed  "Primitive,"  who  invokes  the  "shades  of  Allan  and  eloquence  of  Newton  " 
against  this  attempted  undoing  of  their  work.  "Just  because  a  few  interested 
labor  busybodies  have  got  it  into  their  heads  that  they  can  run  a  cheap-jack 
show  for  every  department  of  our  trade  with  the  same  effect  as  our  great  combina- 
tion, we  are  to  drop  our  arms,  pull  down  our  socks,  hide  our  tail  under  our 
nether  parts,  and  shout  'peccavi.'  .  .  .  Sectional  societies  for  militant  purposes 
are  useless,  and  therefore  they  only  exist — where  such  is  practised — as  friendly 
societies.  .  .  .  Amalgamation  is  our  title,  our  war-cry  and  our  principle ;  and 
once  we  admit  that  it  is  necessary  to  '  federate '  with  sectional  societies  we  give 
away  the  whole  case  to  the  enemy.  .  .  .  Federation  with  trades  whose  work- 
shop  practice  is  keenly  distinct  from  our  own  is  a  good  means  to  a  better  end. 


134  Trade  Union  Structure 

If  now,  looking  back  on  the  whole  history  of  organisation 
in  the  engineering  trade,  we  may  be  "  wise  after  the  event," 
we  suggest  that  it  would  have  been  better  if  the  local 
trade  clubs  had  confined  themselves  each  to  a  single  section 
of  engineering  workmen,  and  if  they  had  then  developed  into 
national  societies  of  like  scope.  Had  this  been  the  case,  and 
could  Newton  and  Allan  have  foreseen  the  enormous  growth 
and  increasing  differentiation  of  their  industry,  they  would 
have  advocated,  not  a  single  comprehensive  amalgamation, 
but  a  federation  of  sectional  societies  of  national  extent,  for 
such  purposes  as  were  common  to  the  whole  engineering 
trade.  This  federation  would  have,  in  the  first  instance, 
included  a  great  national  society  of  fitters,  turners,  and 
erectors  on  the  one  hand,  and  smaller  national  societies  of 
smiths  and  pattern-makers  respectively.  And  as  organisa- 
tion proceeded  among  the  brass-workers,  coppersmiths,  and 
machine-workers,  and  as  new  classes  arose,  like  the  electrical 
engineers,  these  could  each  have  been  endowed  with  a 
sufficient  measure  of  Home  Rule,  and  admitted  as  separate 
sections  to  the  federal  union.  This  federal  union  might  then 
have  combined  in  a  wider  and  looser  federation,  for  specified 
purposes,  with  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  the 
Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders,  the  Associated  Shipwrights' 
Society,  and  the  other  organisations  interested  in  the  great 
industry  of  iron  steamship  building  and  equipping.1 

One  practical  precept  emerges  from  our  consideration  of 
all  these  forms  of  association.  It  is  a  fundamental  condi- 
tion of  stable  and  successful  federal  action  that  the  degree 
of  union  between  the  constituent  bodies  should  correspond 
strictly  with  the  degree  of  their  unity  of  interest.  This  will 

Federation  with  trades  whose  shop  practice  is  similar,  whose  interests  are 
identical,  and  who  ought  to  be  with  us  in  every  fight,  is  a  maudlin  means  to  a 
general  fizzle."  The  question  is  now  (August  1897)  a  subject  of  keen  debate  in 
the  society. 

1  The  several  national  societies  of  Carpenters,  Plumbers,  Painters,  Cabinet- 
makers, etc.,  would,  in  respect  of  their  members  working  in  shipbuilding  yards, 
also  join  this  Federation  ;  whilst  they  would,  at  the  same"  time,  continue  to  be  in 
closer  federal  union  with  the  Bricklayers,  Stonemasons,  and  other  societies  of 
building  operatives. 


Interunion  Relations  135 

be  most  easily  recognised  on  the  financial  side.  We  have 
already  more  than  once  adverted  to  the  fact  that  a  scale 
of  contributions  and  benefits,  which  would  suit  the  require- 
ments of  one  class,  might  be  entirely  out  of  the  reach  of 
other  sections,  whose  co-operation  was  nevertheless  indis- 
pensable for  effective  common  action.  But  this  is  not  all. 
We  have  to  deal,  not  only  with  classes  differing  in  the 
amount  of  their  respective  incomes,  but  also  with  wide 
divergences  between  the  ways  in  which  the  several  classes 
need  to  lay  out  their  incomes.  The  amount  levied  by  the 
federal  body  for  the  common  purse  must  therefore  not  only 
be  strictly  limited  to  the  cost  of  the  services  in  which  all 
the  constituent  bodies  have  an  identical  interest,  but  must 
also  not  exceed,  in  any  case,  the  amount  which  the  poorest 
section  finds  it  advantageous  to  expend  on  these  services. 

But  our  precept  has  a  more  subtle  application  to  the 
aims  and  policy  of  the  federal  body,  and  to  the  manner  in 
which  its  decisions  are  arrived  at.  The  permanence  of  the 
federation  will  be  seriously  menaced  if  it  pursues  any  course 
of  action  which,  though  beneficial  to  the  majority  of  its 
constituent  bodies,  is  injurious  to  any  one  among  them. 
The  constituent  bodies  came  together,  at  the  outset,  for 
the  promotion  of  purposes  desired,  not  merely  by  a 
majority,  but  by  all  of  them  ;  and  it  is  a  violation  of  the 
implied  contract  between  them  to  use  the  federal  force, 
towards  the  creation  of  which  all  have  contributed,  in  a 
manner  inimical  to  any  one  of  them.  This  means  that, 
where  the  interests  diverge,  any  federal  decision  must  be 
essentially  the  result  of  consultation  between  the  representa- 
tives of  the  several  sections,  with  a  view  of  discovering  the 
"  greatest  common  measure."  These  issues  must,  therefore, 
never  be  decided  merely  by  counting  votes.  So  long  as  the 
questions  dealt  with  affect  all  the  constituents  in  approxi- 
mately the  same  manner,  mere  differences  of  opinion  as  to 
projects  or  methods  may  safely  be  decided  by  a  majority 
vote.  If  the  results  are,  in  fact,  advantageous,  the  dis- 
approval of  the  minority  will  quickly  evaporate ;  if,  on  the 


136  Trade  Union  S true  litre 

other  hand,  the  results  prove  to  be  disadvantageous,  the 
dissentients  will  themselves  become  the  dominant  force.  In 
either  case  no  permanent  cleavage  is  caused.  But  if  the 
difference  of  opinion  between  the  majority  and  the  minority 
arises  from  a  real  divergence  of  sectional  interests,  and  is 
therefore  fortified  by  the  event,  any  attempt  on  the  part  of 
the  majority  to  force  its  will  on  the  minority  will,  in  a 
voluntary  federation,  lead  to  secession. 

Thus,  we  are  led  insensibly  to  a  whole  theory  of  "  pro- 
portional representation"  in  federal  constitutions.  In  a  homo- 
geneous association,  where  no  important  divergence  of  actual 
interest  can  exist,  the  supreme  governing  authority  can  safely 
be  elected,  and  fundamental  issues  can  safely  be  decided,  by 
mere  counting  of  heads.  Such  an  association  will  naturally 
adopt  a  representative  system  based  on  universal  suffrage 
and  equal  electoral  districts.  But  when  in  any  federal  body 
we  have  a  combination  of  sections  of  unequal  numerical 
strength,  having  different  interests,  decisions  cannot  safely 
be  left  to  representatives  elected  or  voting  according  to  the 
numerical  membership  of  the  constituent  bodies.  For  this, 
in  effect,  would  often  mean  giving  a  decisive  voice  to  the 
members  of  the  largest  section^  or  to  those  of  the  two  or 
three  larger  sections,  without  the  smaller  sections  having  any 
effective  voting  influence  on  the  result.  Any  such  arrange- 
ment seldom  fails  to  produce  cleavage  and  eventual  secession, 
as  the  members  of  the  dominant  sections  naturally  vote  for 
their  own  interest.  It  is  therefore  preferable,  as  a  means  of 
securing  the  permanence  of  the  federation,  that  the  represen- 
tation of  the  constituent  bodies  should  not  be  exactly  propor- 
tionate to  their  respective  memberships.  The  representative 
system  of  a  federation  should,  in  fact,  like  its  finances,  vary 
with  the  degree  to  which  the  interests  of  the  constituent 
bodies  are  really  identical.  Wherever  interests  are  divergent, 
the  scale  must  at  any  rate  be  so  arranged  that  no  one  con- 
stituent, however  large,  can  outvote  the  remainder ;  and, 
indeed,  so  that  no  two  or  three  of  the  larger  constituents 
could,  by  mutual  agreement,  swamp  all  their  colleagues.  If 


Inter  union  Relations  137 

for  instance,  it  is  proposed  to  federate  all  the  national  unions 
in  the  engineering  trade,  it  would  be  unwise  for  the  Amalga- 
mated Society  of  Engineers  to  claim  proportional  represen- 
tation for  its  87,000  members,  mainly  fitters  and  turners, 
as  compared  with  the  10,000  pattern-makers,  smiths,  and 
machine -workers  divided  among  three  sectional  societies. 
And  when  a  federation  includes  a  large  number  of  very 
different  constituents,  and  exists  for  common  purposes  so 
limited  as  to  bear  only  a  small  proportion  to  the  particular 
interests  of  the  several  sections,  it  may  be  desirable  frankly 
to  give  up  all  idea  of  representation  according  to  member- 
ship, and  to  accord  to  each  constituent  an  equal  voice. 
Hence  the  founders  of  the  Federation  of  the  Engineering 
and  Shipbuilding  Trades  exercised,  in  our  opinion,  a  wise 
discretion  when  they  accorded  to  the  9000  members  of  the 
Operative  Plumbers'  Society  exactly  the  same  representation 
and  voting  power  as  is  enjoyed  by  the  41,000  members  of 
the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  or  by  the  49,000  members 
of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Carpenters.  A  federal  body 
of  this  kind,  formed  only  for  certain  definite  purposes,  and 
composed  of  unions  with  distinct  and  sometimes  divergent 
interests,  stands  at  the  opposite  end  of  the  scale  from  the 
homogeneous  "  amalgamated  "  society.  The  representatives 
of  the  constituent  bodies  meet  for  the  composing  of  mutual 
differences  and  the  discovery  of  common  interests.  They 
resemble,  in  fact,  ambassadors  who  convey  the  desires  of  their 
respective  sovereign  states,  contribute  their  special  knowledge 
to  the  common  council,  but  are  unable  to  promise  obedience 
to  the  federal  decision,  unless  it  commends  itself  as  a  suit- 
able compromise,  or  carries  with  it  the  weight  of  an  almost 
unanimous  consensus  of  opinion.1 

The  problem  of  finding  a  stable  unit  of  government  and 
of  determining  the  relation  between  superior  and  subordinate 
authorities  seems,  therefore,  to  be  in  a  fair  way  of  solution 

1  We  revert  to  these  considerations  when,  in  describing  the  Trade  Union 
machinery  for  political  action,  we  come  to  deal  with  such  federations  as  the 
Trade  Union  Congress  and  the  local  Trades  Councils. 


138  Trade  Union  Structure 

in  the  Trade  Union  world.  With  the  ever  -  increasing 
mobility  of  labor  and  extension  of  industry,  the  local  trade 
club  has  had  to  give  place  to  a  combination  of  national 
extent.  So  long  as  the  craft  or  occupation  is  fairly  uniform 
from  one  end  of  the  kingdom  to  the  other,  the  geographical 
boundaries  of  the  autonomous  state  must,  fn  the  Trade 
Union  world,  ultimately  coincide  with  those  of  the  nation 
itself.  We  have  seen,  too,  how  inevitably  the  growth  of 
national  Trade  Unions  involves,  for  strategic,  and  what  may 
be  called  military  reasons,  the  reduction  of  local  autonomy 
to  a  minimum,  and  the  complete  centralisation  of  all  financial, 
and  therefore  of  all  executive  government  at  the  national 
headquarters.  This  tendency  is  strengthened  by  economic 
considerations  which  we  shall  develop  in  a  subsequent 
chapter.  If  the  Trade  Union  is  to  have  any  success  in 
its  main  function  of  improving  the  circumstances  of  its 
members'  employment,  it  must  build  up  a  dyke  of  a  uniform 
minimum  of  conditions  for  identical  work  throughout  the 
kingdom.  This  uniformity  of  conditions,  or,  indeed,  any 
industrial  influence  whatsoever,  implies  a  certain  uniformity 
and  consistency  of  trade  policy,  which  is  only  rendered 
possible  by  centralisation  of  administration.  So  far,  our 
conclusions  lead,  it  would  seem,  to  the  absolute  simplicity 
of  one  all-embracing  centralised  autocracy.  But,  in  the 
Trade  Union  world,  the  problem  of  harmonising  local  ad- 
ministration and  central  control,  which  for  a  moment  we 
seemed  happily  to  have  got  rid  of,  comes  back  in  an  even 
more  intractable  form.  The  very  aim  of  uniformity  of  con- 
ditions, the  very  fact  that  uniformity  of  trade  policy  is 
indispensable  to  efficiency,  makes  it  almost  impossible  to 
combine  in  a  single  organisation,  with  a  common  purse,  a 
common  executive,  and  a  common  staff  of  salaried  officials, 
men  of  widely  different  occupations  and  grades  of  skill, 
widely  different  Standards  of  Life  and  industrial  needs,  or 
widely  different  numerical  strengths  and  strategic  oppor- 
tunities. A  Trade  Union  is  essentially  an  organisation  for 
securing  certain  concrete  and  definite  advantages  for  all  its 


Internnion  Relations  139 

members — advantages  which  differ  from  trade  to  trade 
according  to  its  technical  processes,  its  economic  position, 
and,  it  may  be,  the  geographical  situation  in  which  it  is 
carried  on.  Hence  all  the  attempts  at  "  General  Unions " 
have,  in  our  view,  been  inevitably  foredoomed  to  failure. 
The  hundreds  of  thousands  of  the  working  class  who  joined 
the  "Grand  National  Consolidated  Trades  Union  "in  1833-34 
came  together,  it  is  true,  on  a  common  basis  of  human  brother- 
hood, and  with  a  common  faith  in  the  need  for  a  radical 
reconstruction  of  society.  But  instead  of  inaugurating  a 
"  New  Moral  World,"  either  by  precept  or  by  political  revolu- 
tion, they  found  themselves  as  a  Trade  Union,  fighting  the 
employers  in  the  Lancashire  cotton  mills  to  get  shorter 
hours  of  labor,  in  the  Leeds  cloth  trade  to  obtain  definite 
piecework  rates,  in  the  London  building  trade  to  do  away 
with  piecework  altogether,  in  Liverpool  to  abolish  the  sub- 
contractor, in  the  hosiery  trade  to  escape  from  truck  and 
deductions.  Each  trade,  in  short,  translated  "  human  brother- 
hood "  into  the  remedying  of  its  own  particular  technical 
grievance,  and  the  central  executive  was  quite  unable  to 
check  the  accuracy  of  the  translation.  The  whole  history 
of  Trade  Unionism  confirms  the  inference  that  a  Trade 
Union,  formed  as  it  is,  for  the  distinct  purpose  of  obtaining 
concrete  and  definite  material  improvements  in  the  conditions 
of  its  members'  employment,  cannot,  in  its  simplest  form, 
safely  extend  beyond  the  area  within  which  those  identical 
improvements  are  shared  by  all  its  members — cannot  spread, 
that  is  to  say,  beyond  the  boundaries  of  a  single  occupa- 
tion. But  the  discovery  of  this  simple  unit  of  government 
does  not  exhaust  the  problem.  Whilst  the  differences 
between  the  sections  render  complete  amalgamation  im- 
practicable, their  identity  in  other  interests  makes  some  bond 
of  union  imperative.  The  most  efficient  form  of  Trade 
Union  organisation  is  therefore  one  in  which  the  several 
sections  can  be  united  for  the  purposes  that  they  have  in 
common,  to  the  extent  to  which  identity  of  interest  prevails, 
and  no  further,  whilst  at  the  same  time  each  section  preserves 


140  Trade  Union  Structure 

complete  autonomy  wherever  its  interests  or  purposes  diverge 
from  those  of  its  allies.  But  this  is  only  another  form  of 
the  difficult  political  problem  of  the  relation  of  supreme  to 
subordinate  authorities.  Whilst  the  student  of  political 
democracy  has  been  grappling  with  the  question  of  how  to 
distribute  administration  between  central  and  local  author- 
ities, the  unlettered  statesmen  of  the  Trade  Union  world 
have  had  to  decide  the  still  more  difficult  issue  of  how  to 
distribute  power  between  general  and  sectional  industrial 
combinations,  both  of  national  extent.  The  solution  has 
been  found  in  a  series  of  widening  and  cross-cutting  federa- 
tions, each  of  which  combines,  to  the  extent  only  of  its  own 
particular  objects,  those  organisations  which  are  conscious 
of  their  identity  of  purpose.  Instead  of  a  simple  form  of 
democratic  organisation  we  get,  therefore,  one  of  extreme 
complexity.  Where  the  difficulties  of  the  problem  have 
been  rightly  apprehended,  and  the  whole  industry  has  been 
organised  on  what  may  be  called  a  single  plane,  the  result 
may  be,  as  in  the  case  of  the  Cotton  Operatives,  a  complex 
but  harmoniously  working  democratic  machine  of  remarkable 
efficiency  and  stability.  Where,  on  the  other  hand,  the 
industry  has  been  organised  on  incompatible  bases,  as  among 
the  Engineers,  we  find  a  complicated  tangle  of  relationships 
producing  rivalry  and  antagonism,  in  which  effective  common 
action,  even  for  such  purposes  as  are  common  to  all  sections, 
becomes  almost  impossible. 

Trade  Union  organisation,  if  it  is  to  reach  its  highest 
possible  efficiency,  must  therefore  assume  a  federal  form. 
Instead  of  a  supreme  central  government,  delegating  parts 
of  its  power  to  subordinate  local  authorities,  we  may  expect 
to  see  the  Trade  Union  world  developing  into  an  elaborate 
series  of  federations,  among  which  it  will  be  difficult  to 
decide  where  the  sovereignty  really  resides.  Where  the 
several  sections  closely  resemble  each  other  in  their  cir- 
cumstances and  needs,  where  their  common  purposes  are 
relatively  numerous  and  important,  and  where,  as  a  result, 
individual  secession  and  subsequent  isolation  would  be 


Interunion  Relations  141 

dangerous,  the  federal  tie  will  be  strong,  and  the  federal 
government  will,  in  effect,  become  the  supreme  authority. 
At  the  other  end  of  the  scale  will  stand  those  federations, 
little  more  than  opportunities  for  consultation,  in  which 
the  contracting  parties  retain  each  a  real  autonomy,  and 
use  the  federal  executive  as  a  convenient,  but  strictly 
subordinate  machinery  for  securing  those  limited  purposes 
that  they  have  in  common.  And  we  have  ventured  to 
suggest,  as  an  interesting  corollary,  that  the  basis  of  re- 
presentation should,  in  all  these  constitutions,  vary  accord- 
ing to  the  character  of  the  bond  of  union,  representation 
proportionate  to  membership  being  perfectly  applicable  only 
to  a  homogeneous  organisation,  and  decreasing  in  suitability 
with  every  degree  of  dissimilarity  between  the  constituent 
bodies.  Where  the  sectional  interests  are  not  only  distinct, 
but  may,  in  certain  cases,  be  even  antagonistic,  as,  for 
instance,  in  industries  subject  to  demarcation  disputes,  rule 
by  majority  vote  must  be  frankly  abandoned,  and  the  repre- 
sentatives of  societies  widely  differing  in  numerical  strength 
must,  under  penalty  of  common  failure,  consent  to  meet 
on  equal  terms,  to  discover,  by  consultation,  how  best  to 
conciliate  the  interests  of  all. 


PART    II 

TRADE    UNION    FUNCTION 


INTRODUCTION 

"THE  chief  object  of  our  society  is  to  elevate  the  social 
position  of  our  members,"  is  the  comprehensive  truism  by 
which  the  ordinary  Trade  Union  defines  its  function.  This 
simple  assertion,  of  what  we  may  term  "  corporate  self-help," 
is,  in  many  of  the  older  unions,  embellished  by  rhetorical 
appeals  to  the  brotherhood  of  man,  and  realistic  descriptions 
of  the  precarious  position  of  the  weekly  wage-earners.  Thus 
the  "  main  principle  "  that  actuated  the  "  originators  "  of  the 
Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders  "  was  that  of  systematic 
organisation,  and  the  desire  of  forming  a  bond  of  brotherhood 
and  sympathy  throughout  the  trade,  in  order  that  those  who, 
by  honest  labor,  obtained  a  livelihood  in  this  particular 
branch  of  industry  might,  in  their  combined  capacity,  more 
successfully  compete  against  the  undue  and  unfair  encroach- 
ments of  capital  than  could  possibly  be  the  case  by  any 
number  of  workmen  when  acting  individually."  l  "  We  are 
willing  to  admit,"  observe  the  founders  of  the  Amalgamated 
Society  of  Engineers,  "  that  whilst  in  constant  employment 
our  members  may  be  able  to  obtain  all  the  necessaries,  and 
perhaps  some  of  the  luxuries  of  life.  .  .  .  Notwithstanding 
all  this,  there  is  a  fear  always  prominent  on  the  mind  of  him 
who  thinks  of  the  future  that  it  may  not  continue,  that  to- 
morrow may  see  him  out  of  employment,  his  nicely-arranged 

1  Rtiles  of  the  Friendly  Ironmoulders'  [now  Ironfounders']  Society,  instituted 
for  the  purpose  of  muttial  relief  in  cases  of  old  age,  sickness,  and  infirmity,  and 
for  the  burial  of  their  dead :  "Made  at  Bolton,  igth  June  1809.  Allowed 
at  Quarter  Sessions,  igth  July  1809"  (Bolton,  1809);  see  edition  of  1891, 
preface. 

VOL.  I  If 


146  Trade  Union  Function 

matters  for  domestic  comfort  overthrown,  and  his  hopes  of 
being  able,  in  a  few  years,  by  constant  attention  and  frugality, 
to  occupy  a  more  permanent  position,  proved  only  to  be  a 
dream.  How  much  is  contained  in  that  word  continuance, 
and  how  necessary  to  make  it  a  leading  principle  of  our 
association  ! " 

But  these  descriptions  of  the  ultimate  objects  of  working- 
class  organisation  afford  us  little  clue  to  the  actual  operation 
of  Trade  Unionism.  The  Trade  Unionists  of  our  own 
generation  are  more  explicit.  With  dry  and  ungrammatical 
precision  the  great  modern  unions  give  as  their  "  Objects  " 
long  strings  of  specific  proposals,  in  which  are  incidentally 
revealed,  with  perfect  frankness,  the  means  relied  upon  to 
achieve  these  ends.  The  Amalgamated  Association  of  Opera- 
tive Cotton-spinners  "  is  formed  to  secure  to  all  its  members 
the  fair  reward  of  their  labor  ;  to  provide  for  the  settlement 
in  a  conciliatory  manner  of  disputes  between  employer  and 
employed,  so  that  a  cessation  of  work  may  be  avoided  ;  the 
enforcement  of  the  Factory  Acts  or  other  legislative  enact- 
ments for  the  protection  of  labor ;  to  afford  pecuniary 
assistance  to  any  member  who  may  be  victimised  or  without 
employment  in  consequence  of  a  dispute  or  lock-out  or  when 
disabled  by  accident."2  The  Miners'  Federation  of  Great 
Britain  declares  that  its  objects  of  association  "  are  to  take 
into  consideration  the  question  of  trade  and  wages,  and  to 
protect  miners  generally  ;  to  seek  to  secure  mining  legislation 
affecting  all  miners  connected  with  this  Federation  ;  to  call 
conferences  to  deal  with  questions  affecting  miners,  both  of  a 
trade,  wage,  and  legislative  character ;  to  seek  and  obtain  an 
eight  hours'  day  from  bank  to  bank  in  all  mines  for  all 
persons  working  underground  ;  to  deal  with  and  watch  all 
inquests  upon  persons  killed  in  the  mines  where  more 
than  three  persons  are  killed  by  any  one  accident ;  to  seek 

1  The  original  Rules  and  Regulations  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers 
(London,  1851),  made  at  Birmingham,  September  1850. 

2  Rules  of  the  Amalgamated  Association  cf  Operative  Cotton-spinners  (Man- 
chester, 1891). 


Introduction  147 

to  obtain  compensation  where  more  than  three  persons  are 
injured  or  killed  in  any  one  accident,  in  all  cases  where 
counties,  federations,  or  districts  have  to  appeal,  or  are 
appealed  against,  from  decisions  in  the  lower  courts."  l  The 
National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  (established 
1874)  declares  that  "The  objects  of  the  union  are:  the 
establishment  of  a  central  fund  for  the  protection  of  members 
and  advancement  of  wages  ;  the  establishment  of  healthy  and 
proper  workshops,  the  employers  to  find  room,  grindery, 
fixtures,  fire,  and  gas,  free  of  charge  ;  the  establishment,  as 
far  as  practicable,  of  a  uniform  rate  of  wages  for  the  same 
class  of  work  throughout  the  union  ;  to  abolish  sweaters  and 
control  the  system  of  apprentices ;  to  reduce  the  hours  of 
labor ;  to  assist  members  who  are  compelled  to  travel  in 
search  of  employment ;  the  introduction  of  Industrial  Co- 
operation in  our  trade  ;  the  use  of  all  legitimate  means  for 
the  moral,  social,  educational,  and  political  advancement  of 
its  members  ;  also  to  make  provision  for  the  union  being 
represented  by  a  Parliamentary  Agent ;  to  raise  funds  for  the 
mutual  support  of  its  members  in  time  of  sickness,  and  for 
the  burial  of  deceased  members  and  their  wives  ;  to  establish 
a  system  of  inter-communication  with  the  Boot  and  Shoe 
Operatives  of  other  countries."  2  Finally,  we  may  cite  the 
most  prominent  and  successful  of  the  so-called  "  new  unions," 
formed  in  the  great  uprising  of  1889.  The  rules  of  the 
National  Union  of  Gasworkers  and  General  Laborers  state 
that  "  The  objects  of  the  union  are  to  shorten  the  hours  of 
labor,  to  obtain  a  legal  eight  hours'  working  day  or  forty-eight 
hours'  week  ;  to  abolish,  wherever  possible,  overtime  and  Sun- 
day labor,  and  where  this  is  not  possible,  to  obtain  payment 
at  a  higher  rate  ;  to  abolish  piecework  ;  to  raise  wages,  and 
where  women  do  the  same  work  as  men,  to  obtain  for  them 
the  same  wages  as  paid  the  men  ;  to  enforce  the  provisions 
of  the  Truck  Acts  in  their  entirety ;  to  abolish  the  present 
system  of  contracts  and  agreements  between  employers  and 

1  Miners'  Federation  of  Great  Britain — Kttles  (Openshaw,  1893). 
2  Rules  of  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  (Leicester,  1892). 


148  Trade  Union  Function 

employed  ;  to  settle  all  labor  disputes  by  amicable  agree- 
ment whenever  possible  ;  to  obtain  equality  of  employers  and 
employed  before  the  law  ;  to  obtain  legislation  for  the  better- 
ing of  the  lives  of  the  working  class  ;  to  secure  the  return  of 
members  of  the  union  to  vestries,  school  boards,  boards  of 
guardians,  municipal  bodies,  and  to  Parliament,  provided  such 
candidates  are  pledged  to  the  collective  ownership  of  the 
means  of  production,  distribution,  and  exchange  ;  to  set  aside 
annually  a  maximum  sum  of  £200,  to  be  used  solely  for  the 
purpose  of  helping  to  return  and  maintain  members  on  public 
representative  bodies  ;  to  assist  similar  organisations  having 
the  same  objects  as  herein  stated."  l 

We  must,  however,  not  look  to  the  formal  rules  or 
rhetorical  preambles  for  a  scientific  or  complete  account  of 
Trade  Union  action.  Drafted  originally  by  enthusiastic 
pioneers,  copied  and  recopied  by  successive  revising  com- 
mittees, the  printed  constitutions  of  working-class  associa- 
tions represent  rather  the  aspirations  than  the  everyday 
action  of  the  members.  More  trustworthy  data  may  be 
obtained  from  a  scrutiny  of  the  cash  accounts,  or  from  a 
close  study  of  the  voluminous  internal  literature  of  the 
unions — the  monthly,  quarterly,  and  yearly  reports  of  the 
central  executives,  the  frequent  official  circulars  on  particular 
questions,  and  the  elaborate  verbatim  notes  of  conferences 
and  joint  committees.  The  printed  documents  circulated  by 
some  societies  include  the  diary  of  their  principal  trade 
official,  detailing  his  day-by-day  negotiation  with  employers.2 
Other  unions  publish  to  their  members  periodical  reports 
from  their  district  delegates  stationed  in  the  principal  indus- 
trial centres,  containing  valuable  information  as  to  the  move- 
ments of  trade,  graphic  accounts  of  disputes  with  employers 
or  other  societies,  and  appeals  for  guidance  as  to  the  policy  to 
be  pursued.  To  the  student  of  sociology  this  literature — 
poured  out  to  the  extent  of  hundreds  of  volumes  annually— 

J  Rules  of  the  National  Union  of  Gasworkers  and  General  Laborers  of  Great 
Britain  and  Ireland  (London,  1894). 

2  See  the  extracts  printed  in  the  chapter  on  "The  Standard  Rate," 


Introduction  \  49 

is  of  fascinating  interest.  It  affords  a  graphic  picture  of  the 
actual  structure  and  working  of  the  modern  world  of  manu- 
facturing industry,  with  its  constant  changes  of  process  and 
shiftings  of  trade.  It  lays  bare,  more  completely  than  any 
other  records  known  to  us,  the  real  nature  and  action  of 
democratic  organisation  in  the  Anglo-Saxon  race.  And, 
what  is  most  relevant  to  our  present  purpose,  it  reveals,  with 
all  the  pathos  of  success  and  failure,  the  working  of  the 
various  Trade  Union  Methods  and  Regulations  with  the 
underlying  assumptions  as  to  social  expediency  on  which 
they  are  based. 

But  documents,  however  frank  and  confidential,  are  apt  to 
distort  facts  as  well  as  to  display  them.  A  heated  recrimi- 
nation between  a  local  official  and  the  general  secretary,  a 
dispute  about  the  wages  on  a  new  process,  affecting  only  a 
tiny  minority  of  the  members,  or  a  Parliamentary  agitation 
for  a  new  clause  in  the  Factory  Acts  will  loom  large  in  the 
proceedings  of  the  year,  and  may  seem  to  represent  the  bulk 
of  the  union's  activity.  Meanwhile,  the  branches  may  have 
been  engaged  in  a  peaceful  but  successful  maintenance  of 
their  old-standing  Working  Rules,  or  a  new  regulation  may 
silently  have  become  habitual,  or  an  old  one  silently  dropped, 
without  this  action  on  the  part  of  the  majority  of  the 
members  rising  to  the  surface  in  any  document  whatsoever, 
public  or  private.  To  complete  the  knowledge  yielded  by 
documents,  the  student  must  watch  the  men  at  work,  and 
discuss  the  application  of  particular  regulations  with  em- 
ployers, managers,  and  foremen — not  omitting  the  factory 
inspector  and  the  secretary  to  the  Employers'  Association — 
he  must  listen  to  the  objections  of  the  small  master  and  the 
blackleg  ;  above  all,  he  must  attend  the  inside  meetings  of 
branches  and  district  committees,  where  the  points  at  issue 
are  discussed  in  technical  detail  with  a  frank  explicitness 
which  is  untrammelled  either  by  the  prejudices  of  the  rank 
and  file  or  the  fear  of  the  enemy. 

This  combined  plan  of  studying  documents  and  observing 
men  is  the  one  that  we  have,  during  our  six  years'  investi- 


150  Trade  Union  Function 

gation,  attempted  to  follow.  In  the  ensuing  chapters  we 
endeavor  to  place  before  the  reader  an  accurate  descrip- 
tion of  the  Methods  and  Regulations  actually  practised  by 
British  Trade  Unionism.  We  shall  see  the  Trade  Unionists, 
from  the  beginning  of  the  eighteenth  century  down  to  the 
present  day,  enforcing  their  Regulations  by  three  distinct 
instruments  or  levers,  which  we  distinguish  as  the  Method 
of  Mutual  Insurance,  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining, 
and  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment.  From  the  Methods 
used  to  enforce  the  Regulations,  we  shall  pass  to  the  Regu- 
lations themselves.  These  we  shall  find  grouping  themselves, 
notwithstanding  an  almost  infinite  variety  of  technical  detail, 
under  seven  main  heads — the  Standard  Rate,  the  Normal 
Day,  Sanitation  and  Safety,  New  Processes  and  Machinery, 
Continuity  of  Employment,  the  Entrance  into  a  Trade, 
and  the  Right  to  a  Trade — all  of  which  we  examine  in 
separate  chapters.  This  will  lead  us  to  the  Implications  of 
Trade  Unionism — certain  practical  outgrowths  and  necessary 
consequences  of  Trade  Union  policy  which  require  elucida- 
dation.  Finally,  we  shall  bring  into  light  the  Assumptions 
of  Trade  Unionism — the  fundamental  prejudices,  opinions,  or 
judgments  lying  at  the  root  of  Trade  Union  policy — an 
analysis  of  which  will  serve  at  once  to  explain  and  to  sum- 
marise the  various  forms  of  Trade  Union  action. 

In  the  course  of  this  comprehensive  description  of  Trade 
Unionism  as  it  is,  we  shall  not  abstain  from  incidentally 
criticising  the  various  Methods  and  Regulations,  and  the 
different  types  of  Trade  Union  policy,  in  respect  of  the 
success  or  failure  of  Trade  Unions  to  apply  them  to  the  facts 
of  modern  life.  But  in  this  part  of  our  book  we  care- 
fully avoid  any  discussion  as  to  the  effects  of  Trade  Unionism 
upon  industry,  and,  above  all,  we  make  no  attempt  to  decide 
whether  it  has  or  has  not  resulted  in  effectively  raising 
wages,  or  otherwise  improving  the  conditions  of  employment. 
We  venture  to  think  that  there  can  be  no  useful  discussion 
of  the  economic  validity  of  Trade  Unionism  until  the  student 
has  first  surveyed  its  actual  contents.  Our  examination  of 


Introduction  1 5 1 

the  theory  of  trade  combination — the  possibility,  by  deliberate 
common  action,  of  altering  the  conditions  of  employment ; 
the  effect  of  the  various  Methods  and  Regulations  upon  the 
efficiency  of  production  and  the  distribution  of  wealth  ;  and 
the  ultimate  social  expediency  of  exchanging  a  system  of 
unfettered  individual  competition  for  one  of  collective  regula- 
tion— in  a  word,  our  judgment  upon  Trade  Unionism  as  a 
whole — we  reserve  for  the  third  and  final  part  of  this  book. 


CHAPTER    I 

THE    METHOD    OF    MUTUAL    INSURANCE 

IN  a  certain  sense  it  would  not  be  difficult  to  regard  all  the 
activities  of  Trade  Unionism  as  forms  of  Mutual  Insurance. 
Whether  the  purpose  be  the  fixing  of  a  list  of  piecework 
prices,  the  promotion  of  a  new  factory  bill,  or  the  defence 
of  a  member  against  a  prosecution  for  picketing,  we  see 
the  contributions,  subscribed  equally  in  the  past  by  all  the 
members,  applied  in  ways  which  benefit  unequally  particular 
individuals  or  particular  sections  among  them,  independently 
of  the  amount  which  these  individuals  or  sections  may  them- 
selves have  contributed.  But  this  interpretation  of  insurance 
would  cover,  not  Trade  Unionism  alone,  but  practically  every 
form  of  collective  action,  including  citizenship  itself.  By 
the  phrase  "  Mutual  Insurance,"  as  one  of  the  Methods  of 
Trade  Unionism,  we  understand  only  the  provision  of  a 
fund  by  common  subscription  to  insure  against  casualties  ; 
to  provide  maintenance,  that  is  to  say,  in  cases  in  which  a 
member  is  deprived  of  his  livelihood  by  causes  over  which 
neither  he  nor  the  union  has  any  control.  This  obviously 
covers  the  "  benevolent "  or  friendly  society  side  of  Trade 
Unionism,  such  as  the  provision  of  sick  pay,  accident  benefit, 
and  superannuation  allowance,  together  with  "  burial  money," 
and  such  allowances  as  that  made  to  members  of  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Tailors  who  are  prevented  from 
working  by  the  sanitary  authorities,  owing  to  the  presence 
of  infectious  disease  in  their  homes.  But  it  includes  also 


The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance  1 5  3 

what  are  often  termed  "  trade  "  benefits  ;  grants  for  replacing 
tools  lost  by  theft  or  fire,  and  "  out-of-work  pay,"  from  the 
old-fashioned  "tramping  card  "  to  the  modern  "  donation  " 
given  when  a  member  loses  his  employment  by  the  tem- 
porary breakdown  of  machinery  or  "  want  of  pit  room,"  by 
the  bankruptcy  of  his  employer  or  the  stoppage  of  a  mill, 
or  merely  in  consequence  of  a  depression  in  trade.  "  The 
simplest  and  universal  function  of  trades  societies,"  it 
was  reported  in  1 860,  "  is  the  enabling  the  workman  to 
maintain  himself  while  casually  out  of  employment,  or 
travelling  in  search  of  it."1  On  the  other  hand,  our 
definition  excludes  all  expenditure  incurred  by  the  union  as 
a  consequence  of  action  voluntarily  undertaken  by  it,  such 
as  the  cost  of  trade  negotiations,  the  "  victim  pay  "  accorded 
to  members  dismissed  for  agitation,  and  the  maintenance  of 
men  on  strike.  These  we  omit  as  more  properly  incidental 
to  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining.  We  also  leave  to 
be  dealt  with  under  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  the 
provision  for  the  legal  aid  of  members  under  the  Employers' 
Liability,  Truck,  or  Factory  Acts. 

Trade  Union  Mutual  Insurance,  thus  defined,  comprises 
two  distinct  classes  of  benefit :  "  Friendly "  and  "  Out  of 
Work."  There  is  an  essential  difference  between  the 
insurance  against  such  physical  and  personal  casualties  as 
sickness,  accident,  and  old  age  on  the  one  hand,  and,  on  the 
other,  the  stoppage  of  income  caused  by  mere  inability  to 
obtain  employment. 

Friendly  Mutual  Insurance,  in  many  industries  the  oldest 
form  of  Trade  Union  activity,  has  been  adopted  by  practically 
every  society  which  has  lasted.  Here  and  there,  at  all  times, 
one  trade  or  another  has,  in  the  first  emergence  of  its 
organisation,  preferred  to  confine  its  action  to  Collective 
Bargaining  or  to  aim  at  Legal  Enactment.2  But  directly 

1  Report  of  the  National  Association  for  the  Promotion  of  Social  Science  on 
Trade  Societies  and  Strikes  (London,  1860),  p.  xx. 

2  See  for  the  so-called   "New   Unionism"  of  1889,  the  History  of  Trade 
Unionism,  pp.  401,  406. 


154  Trade  Union  Function 

the  combination  has  settled  down  to  everyday  life,  we  find 
it  adding  one  or  other  of  the  benefits  of  insurance,  and  often 
developing  into  the  most  comprehensive  Trade  Friendly 
Society.  For  the  past  hundred  years  this  insurance  business 
has  been  steadily  growing,  not  only  in  volume,  but  also  in 
deliberateness  and  regularity. 

In  providing  friendly  benefits  the  Trade  Union  comes 
into  direct  competition  with  the  ordinary  friendly  society 
and  the  industrial  insurance  company.  The  engineer  or 
carpenter  who  joins  his  Trade  Union  might  insure  against 
sickness,  old  age,  and  the  expenses  of  burial,  by  joining  the 
"  Oddfellows  "  and  the  "  Prudential  "  instead.  And  from 
an  actuarial  point  of  view  the  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Engineers  or  Carpenters  is  not  for  a  moment  to  be  com- 
pared with  a  friendly  society  of  good  standing.  Unlike  the 
registered  friendly  society,  the  Trade  Union,  even  if  registered, 
does  not  enter  into  any  legally  binding  contract.  A  Trade 
Union  cannot  be  sued  ;  and  the  members  have  individually 
no  legal  remedy  against  it.  A  member  who  has  paid  for  a 
whole  lifetime  to  the  sick  and  superannuation  funds  may,  at 
any  moment,  be  expelled  and  forfeit  all  claim,  for  reasons 
quite  unconnected  with  his  desire  for  insurance  in  old  age. 
Against  the  decision  of  his  fellow-members  there  is,  in  no 
case,  any  appeal.  Moreover,  the  scale  of  contributions  and 
benefits  may  at  any  time  be  altered,  even  to  the  extent  of 
abolishing  benefits  altogether ;  and  such  alterations  do,  in 
fact,  frequently  take  place,  in  spite  of  all  the  protests  of 
minorities  of  old  members.  And  it  is  no  small  drawback 
to  the  security  of  the  individual  member  that,  in  a  time  of 
trade  depression,  just  when  he  himself  is  probably  poorest, 
he  is  invariably  required  to  pay  extra  levies  to  meet  the 
heavy  Out  of  Work  liabilities,  on  pain  of  being  automatically 
excluded,  and  thus  forfeiting  all  his  insurance.  It  is  a 
further  aggravation  that  in  any  crisis  the  Trade  Union, 
unlike  the  friendly  society,  regards  the  punctual  discharge  of 
its  sick  and  superannuation  liabilities  as  a  distinctly  secondary 
consideration.  The  paramount  requisite  of  an  organisation 


The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance  1 5  5 

professing  to  provide  against  sickness  and  old  age  is  abso- 
lute security  that  the  accumulated  funds  will  be  reserved 
exclusively  to  meet  the  growing  liabilities.  But  in  a  Trade 
Union  there  is  no  guarantee  that  any  of  its  funds  will  be 
reserved  for  this  purpose.  During  a  long  spell  of  trade 
depression  the  whole  accumulated  balance  may  be  spent  in 
maintaining  the  members  out  of  work.  An  extensive  strike 
may,  at  any  time,  drain  the  society  absolutely  dry.  The 
Friendly  Society  of  Operative  Stonemasons,  for  instance, 
has,  during  its  sixty  years'  existence,  twice  been  reduced 
to  absolute  beggary,  in  1841  by  a  prolonged  strike,  and  in 
1879  by  the  severe  depression  in  trade.  A  still  older  and 
richer  union,  the  Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders,  not  only 
spent  every  penny  of  its  funds  in  1879,  but  borrowed  many 
thousands  of  pounds  from  its  members'  individual  savings  to 
meet  the  most  pressing  of  its  liabilities.1  This  "  hole  in  the 
stocking"  is  not  mended  by  any  nominal  allocation  of  a 
certain  part  of  the  income,  or  a  specific  share  of  the  funds, 
to  the  sick  or  superannuation  liabilities.  No  Trade  Union 
ever  dreams  of  putting  any  part  of  its  funds  legally  or 
effectively  out  of  the  control  of  its  members  for  the  time 
being ;  and  when  a  time  of  stress  comes,  the  nominal  alloca- 
tion offers  no  obstacle  to  the  "  borrowing "  of  some  or  all 
the  ear-marked  balance  for  current  purposes.  Trade  Union- 
ists, in  short,  subscribe  their  money  primarily  for  the  main- 
tenance or  improvemervtjof  their  wages  or  other  conditions, 
of  employment :  "onlyafter  this  object  has  been  secured  do  * 
they  expect  or  desire  any  sick  or  other  friendly  benefits,  and 
their  rules  proceed  always  on  the  assumption  that  such 
benefits  are  payable  only  if  and  when  there  is  a  surplus  in 
hand. 

This  entire  want  of  legal  or  financial  security  has 
hitherto  prevented  actuaries  from  giving  serious  considera- 
tion to  the  problems  of  Trade  Union  insurance.2  The 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism ,  pp.  157,  334. 

2  This  lack  of  knowledge  and  absence  of  serious  study  has  not  prevented 
leading  actuaries  from  denouncing  stable  and  well-managed  Trade  Unions  as 


156  Trade  Union  Function 

consequence  is  that  the  Trade  Union  scales  of  contributions 
and  benefits  do  not  rest  on  any  actuarial  basis,  and  represent, 
at  best,  the  empirical  guess-work  of  the  members.  Scarcely 
any  attempt  has  yet  been  made  to  collect  the  data  necessary 

financially  unsound,  even  on  their  friendly  society  side,  and  inevitably  destined  to 
early  bankruptcy.  Before  the  Royal  Commission  of  1867-68,  for  instance,  two 
of  the  principal  actuaries  demonstrated  that  both  the  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Engineers  and  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Carpenters  were  insolvent  to  the 
extent  of  many  hundreds  of  thousands  of  pounds,  and  that  they  were  necessarily 
doomed  to  collapse.  In  spite  of  the  patent  falsification  of  these  prophecies,  and 
the  continued  growth  in  wealth  of  the  great  unions,  similar  denunciations  and 
predictions  are  still  repeated  by  actuarial  authorities  ignorant  of  their  own 
ignorance. 

A  Trade  Union  differs  fundamentally  from  a  friendly  society  or  insurance 
company,  which  undertakes  to  provide  definite  payments  for  a  specified  premium. 
A  Trade  Union  is  not  only  free  at  any  time  to  revise,  or  even  suspend,  its 
benefits  ;  it  can,  and  habitually  does,  increase  its  income  by  levies.  Thus, 
whilst  the  nominal  contribution  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  is  a 
shilling  per  week,  the  actual  amount  received  from  the  members  during  the  ten 
years  1886-95  averaged,  for  the  whole  period,  one  shilling  and  twopence  halfpenny 
per  week  (Eighth  Report  by  the  Chief  Labour  Correspondent  on  Trade  Unions^ 
C.  8232,  1896,  p.  404),  and  the  rules  expressly  provide  that  "when  the  funds 
are  reduced  to  ^3  per  member  the  contributions  shall  be  increased  by  such  sum 
per  week  as  will  sustain  the  funds  at  not  less  than  that  amount"  (Rule  XXV.  of 
edition  of  1896,  p.  121).  A  society  with  such  a  rule  can  obviously  never 
become  insolvent  so  long  as  it  retains  any  members,  and  chooses  to  meet  its 
engagements. 

But  there  is  another  and  no  less  important  difference  in  actuarial  position 
between  a  Trade  Union  and  a  friendly  society.  A  friendly  society  is  rightly 
deemed  unsound  if  the  contributions  paid  by  the  members  when  young  do  not 
enable  a  fund  to  be  accumulated  to  meet  the  greatly  increased  liabilities  for  sick- 
ness, superannuation,  and  burial  as  they  grow  older.  A  society  may  have  cash  in 
hand,  and  yet  be  steering  into  bankruptcy,  if  the  average  age  of  its  members  is 
increasing,  or  might  presently  (by  a  stoppage  of  recruiting)  be  found  to  be 
increasing.  This  rapid  increase  of  liabilities  with  advancing  age  constitutes  what 
insurance  experts  denounce  as  "the  vice  of  assessmentism "  —  the  fallacious 
assumption  that  the  year's  payments  can  safely  be  met  by  the  year's  levies  on  the 
members  for  the  time  being.  But  where  membership  is  universal,  the  average 
age,  and  therefore  the  liabilities,  do  not,  and  cannot,  increase.  If  sick-pay, 
superannuation,  and  burial  were  provided  by  the  State  for  all  citizens,  the  number 
of  cases  year  by  year  would,  from  an  actuarial  point  of  view,  remain  constant,  or 
would  be  affected  only  by  the  slow  and  gradual  changes  in  national  health.  A 
single  trade  is,  in  this  respect,  in  much  the  same  position  as  the  nation,  and  when 
a  Trade  Union  habitually  includes  all  the  operatives  in  its  industry  the  percentage 
of  benefit  cases  is  remarkably  uniform.  Moreover,  even  in  less  universal  organ- 
isations, where  the  motives  for  joining  are  very  largely  unconnected  with 
friendly  benefits,  and  there  is  no  competing  union,  the  result  is  practically  the 
same.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  the  average  age  of  the  members  of  well-established 
Trade  Unions,  so  far  as  this  can  be  ascertained,  remains  remarkably  stable,  and 
seems  to  increase  only  with  the  general  improvement  in  sanitation. 


The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance  1 5  7 

for  a  more  precise  computation  ;  and  even  such  elementary 
facts  as  the  average  age  of  the  members,  or  the  special 
death  rate  or  sickness  rate  of  the  occupation,  are  often 
unknown.  There  is  no  graduation  of  contributions  accord- 
ing to  age,  practically  no  attempt  at  medical  selection  of  can- 
didates for  membership,  and  a  complete  uncertainty  as  to 
what  interest  will  be  received  on  investments,  or  whether  the 
funds  will  be  invested  at  interest  at  all.  In  short,  the  Trade 
Union,  considered  merely  as  a  friendly  society,  does  not 
profess  to  afford  its  members  any  legal  security  or  certain 
guarantee  against  destitution  in  sickness  or  old  age.  Its 
promises  of  superannuation  allowances,  and  even  of  sick  pay, 
are,  in  reality,  conditional  on  there  being  money  left  over 
after  providing  for  other  purposes.  "  The  right  "  [of  members 
to]  "any  benefit,"  wrote  Daniel  Guile,  in  1869,  in  the  name 
of  the  Ironfounders'  Executive,  "  only  exists  as  long  as  the 
Society  has  power  to  pay  it.  Any  determination  of  the 
exact  amount  of  return  a  member  may  rightly  expect  for  a 
particular  amount  of  contribution  rests  upon  averages  of  a 
nature  far  too  abstruse  to  be  entered  upon  here,  and  for 
which,  indeed,  even  the  groundwork  is  wanting."  *  In  face 
of  this  lack  of  security,  and  absence  of  actuarial  basis,  it 
seems  at  first  sight  surprising  that  union  after  union  should 
add  to  its  purely  trade  functions  the  business  of  an  ordinary 
friendly  society.  But,  as  Professor  Beesly  remarked  in  1867, 
"  it  is  much  more  economical  to  depend  upon  one  society 
combining  all  benefits,  than  to  contribute  to  a  friendly 
society  for  sick  and  funeral  benefits,  and  to  a  union  for  tool 
and  accident  benefit  and  trade  purposes."  2  Whether  or  not 
the  ordinary  artisan  appreciates  the  economy  effected  by 
"  concentration  of  management  and  consequent  lessening  of 
working  expenses,"  he  at  any  rate  realises  that  it  is  less 
irksome  to  pay  to  one  club  than  to  several.  But  this  hardly 
explains  the  persistent  advocacy  of  sick  pay  and  superannua- 

1  Monthly  Report  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders,  October  1869. 
*  E.  S.  Beesly,  The  Amalgamated  Society  of  Carpenters  and  Joiners  (London, 
1867),  p.  4. 


1 58  Trade  Union  Function 

tion  allowance  by  experienced  Trade  Union  officials.  Their 
belief  in  the  advantage  of  developing  the  friendly  society 
side  of  Trade  Unionism  rests  frankly  on  the  adventitious 
aid  it  brings  to  working-class  organisation.  The  benefit 
club  side  serves,  in  the  first  place,  as  a  potent  attraction  to 
hesitating  recruits.  To  the  young  man  just  "  out  of  his 
time  "  the  prospect  of  securing  support  in  sickness  or  un- 
employment is  a  greater  inducement  to  join  the  union,  and 
regularly  to  keep  up  his  contributions,  than  the  less  obvious 
advantages  to  be  gained  by  the  trade  combination.  "  It 
helps,"  says  Mr.  George  Howell,  "to  bind  the  members  to 
the  union  when  possibly  other  considerations  might  inter- 
pose to  diminish  the  zeal  of  the  Trade  Unionist  pure  and 
simple."  J 

Moreover,  when,  as  is  usually  the  case,  the  whole  contri- 
bution goes  into  a  common  fund,  the  society  gains  the  advan- 
tage of  an  additional  financial  reserve,  which  can  be  used  in 
support  of  its  trade  policy  in  time  of  need,  and  replaced  as 
opportunity  permits.  Such  great  Trade  Friendly  Societies 
as  the  Boilermakers',  Engineers',  Stonemasons',  and  Iron- 
founders'  have,  as  we  have  seen,  never  hesitated  to  deplete 
their  balances  in  order  to  enable  their  members  to  withstand 
encroachments  on  their  Standard  of  Life.  Thus,  the  addition 
of  friendly  society  benefits,  bringing,  as  it  does,  greatly 
increased  contributions,  enables  the  Trade  Union  to  roll 
up  an  imposing  reserve  fund,  which,  even  if  not  actually 
drawn  upon,  is  found  to  be  an  effective  "  moral  influence  "  in 
negotiations  with  employers. 

We  see,  therefore,  that  the  friendly  society  element 
supplies  to  Trade  Unionism  both  adventitious  attractions 
and  an  adventitious  support.  But  this  is  not  all.  In  a 
strong  and  well-organised  union,  the  existence  of  important 
friendly  benefits  may  become  a  powerful  instrument  for 
maintaining  discipline  among  the  members,  and  for  enforcing 
upon  all  the  decisions  of  the  majority.  If  expulsion  carries 
with  it  the  loss  of  valuable  prospective  benefits,  such,  for 

1    Trade  Unionism,  New  and  Old,  by  George  Howell  (London,  1892),  p.  102. 


The  Method  of  Mutiial  Insurance  159 

instance,  as  superannuation,  it  becomes  a  penalty  of  great 
severity.  Similarly,  when  secession  involves  the  abandon- 
ment of  all  share  in  a  considerable  accumulated  balance,  a 
branch  momentarily  discontented  with  some  decision  of  the 
majority  thinks  twice  before  it  breaks  off  in  a  pet  to  set  up 
as  an  independent  society.  Thus  the  addition  of  friendly 
benefits  has  been,  on  the  whole,  a  great  consolidating  force 
in  Trade  Unionism.  We  can,  therefore,  quite  understand 
why  thoroughgoing  opponents  of  trade  combinations  have, 
like  the  associated  employers  who  came  before  the  Royal 
Commission  in  1867,  vehemently  denounced  the  combination 
of  trade  and  friendly  society  as  illegitimate  and  dangerous.1 

Friendly  benefits  have  yet  another  advantage  from  the 
point  of  view  of  the  Trade  Union  official.  To  the  permanent 
salaried  officer  of  a  great  union,  with  his  time  fully  occupied 
by  his  daily  routine,  it  is  no  small  gain  that  sick  pay  and 
superannuation  allowance  exercise  a  great  effect  in  "  keeping 
the  members  quiet."  This  was  perceived,  as  early  as  1867, 
by  a  shrewd  friend  of  the  great  Amalgamated  Societies,  the 
"  New  Unionism  "  of  that  time.  "  The  importance  of  the 
principle  [of  providing  all  the  usual  benefits  offered  by 
friendly  societies]  will  be  best  understood,"  observes  Professor 
Beesly,  "  by  looking  at  the  character  and  working  of  the 

1  "  The  combination  of  trade  with  benefit  purposes  was  astutely  conceived, 
with  a  view  to  increase  the  strength  of  trade  organisations.  The  benefit  element 
was  first  to  decoy,  and  then  to  control.  The  lure  of  prospective  benefits  having 
attracted  members,  the  dread  of  confiscation  was  to  enforce  obedience." — Trade 
Unionism,  by  James  Stirling  (Glasgow,  1869),  p.  43. 

There  is  absolutely  no  warrant  for  the  accusation — still  often  repeated — that 
the  use  of  all  the  Trade  Union  funds  for  strike  purposes  when  the  members  so 
decide,  amounts,  morally  if  not  legally,  to  malversation.  The  Chief  Registrar  of 
Friendly  Societies,  questioned  on  this  very  point  by  the  Royal  Commission  on 
Labor,  emphatically  upheld  the  Trade  Union  practice.  "The  primary  object  of 
the  Trade  Union,"  said  Mr.  Brabrook,  "  is  protection  of  trade,  and  all  the  rest 
is  merely  subsidiary.  .  .  .  The  great  bulk  of  members  of  Trade  Unions  know 
perfectly  well  that  they  will  not  get  the  benefit  in  sickness  if  their  money  has 
been  previously  spent  in  trade  purposes,  and  they  are  perfectly  willing  it  should 
be  so  spent  if  emergency  or  necessity  arises  "  (Questions  1561-3).  Mr.  J.  M. 
Ludlow,  who  preceded  him  in  office,  entirely  confirmed  this  view.  To  hypothe- 
cate any  Trade  Union  funds  for  benefit  purposes,  he  added,  "might  be  to  the 
ruin  of  the  Trade  Union,  and  therefore  to  the  ruin  of  the  men  who  had  contri- 
buted those  funds"  (Questions  1783-8). 


1 60  Trade  Union  Function 

old-fashioned  unions  in  which  it  is  not  adopted.  The  men 
combine  purely  for  '  trade  purposes.'  The  subscription  is 
insignificant,  sometimes  only  a  penny  a  week.  The  members 
probably  belong  to  the  Oddfellows  or  Foresters  for  the 
benefit  purposes  ;  and  their  financial  tie  to  their  union  being 
so  weak,  they  join  it  or  leave  it  with  equal  carelessness. 
Nevertheless,  small  as  the  subscription  is,  a  fund  will  in 
course  of  time  be  accumulated.  There  is  nothing  to  do  with 
this  fund.  There  it  is,  eating  its  head  off,  so  to  speak.  The 
men  become  impatient  to  use  it ;  so  a  demand  is  made  on 
the  employers,  irrespective  perhaps  of  the  circumstances  of 
the  trade.  A  strike  follows.  The  members  live  on  their 
fund  for  a  few  weeks,  and  when  it  is  exhausted  they  give  in. 
Such  societies  may  be  called  Strike  Societies,  for  they  exist 
for  nothing  else." l  "  A  trade  society  without  friendly 
benefits,"  Mr.  John  Burnett  has  frequently  declared,  "  is 
like  a  standing  army.  It  is  a  constant  menace  to  peace." 
And  thus  we  find  the  employers  of  this  generation  abandon- 
ing the  criticisms  of  their  predecessors  in  1867,  and  reserving 
their  bitterest  denunciations  for  the  purely  trade  society. 

With  regard  to  the  other  branch  of  their  Mutual  Insurance 
business,  the  Trade  Unions  occupy  a  unique  position.  How- 
ever imperfectly  Trade  Unions  may  discharge  the  function  of 
providing  maintenance  for  their  members  when  out  of  work, 
they  undertake  here  a  service  which  must,  in  their  absence, 
remain  unperformed.  No  other  organisation,  whether  com- 
mercial or  philanthropic,  has  yet  come  forward  to  protect 
the  wage-earner  against  the  destitution  arising  from  lack  of 
employment.2  Experience  seems  to  indicate  that  Out  of 

1  E.   S.   Beesly,  The  Amalgamated  Society  of  Carpenters  and  Joiners,  p.    3 
(London,  1867). 

2  Certain  experiments  have  been  made  since  1894  at  Berne,  Basle,  and  St.  Gall 
(Switzerland) ;  at  Cologne  (Germany)  ;  and  at  Bologna  (Italy),  in  the  direction 
of  municipal  insurance  against  unemployment,  either  voluntary  or  compulsory. 
An   account  of  these  experiments,   which   do  not   appear    to    have    been   very 
successful,  will  be  found  in  the  Rapport  sur  la  Question  du  Chdinage,  published 
by  the  French  Government,  Conseil  Superieur  du  Travail  (Paris,  1896,  398  pp.) ; 
and   Circulars  2.   and   5    (Series   B)   of  the  Musee  Social,  Paris,   containing  an 
elaborate  bibliography  ;  to  which  we  can  add  Charles  Raaijmakers,   Verzekering 
tegen  IVerkloosheid  (Amsterdam,  1895). 


The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance  1 6 1 

Work  pay  cannot  be  properly  administered  except  by  bodies 
of  men  belonging  to  the  same  trade  and  working  in  the 
same  establishments.  Therefore  it  is  not  remarkable  that 
Trade  Unions  should  give  most  of  their  attention  to  the 
administration  of  their  Out  of  Work  benefits.  We  find,  in 
fact,  that  although  funeral  benefit  is  almost  universal,  and 
accident  allowance  very  widely  adopted,  these,  like  insurance 
of  tools,  make  up  in  the  aggregate  a  very  small  proportion 
of  the  total  expenditure.  And  though  sick  pay  and  super- 
annuation stand  for  appreciable  sums,  it  is  Out  of  Work 
benefit  which  takes  the  most  important  place  in  the  Mutual 
Insurance  business,  its  limits  being  extended  in  many  instances, 
whilst  others  are  cut  down.1  To  a  middle-class  body  it 
would  seem  natural  to  give  a  kind  of  preferential  lien  on 
the  funds,  to  insure  the  continuance  of  the  weekly  allowances 
to  the  sick  and  superannuated  members  already  on  the  books. 
A  Trade  Union  not  only  refrains  from  taking  this  course, 
but  actually  gives  a  preference,  in  effect,  to  its  Out  of  Work 
payments,  usually  continuing  them  at  the  full  rate,  even 
when  its  funds  are  being  rapidly  exhausted,  until  it  has 
parted  with  its  last  penny.  The  secret  of  this  bias  does 
not  lie  altogether  in  the  immense  difference  in  permanence 
between  middle  class  and  working  class  employment.  The 
main  object  of  the  individual  member  may  be  to  provide 
against  the  personal  distress  which  would  otherwise  be  caused 
to  himself  and  his  family  by  the  stoppage  of  his  weekly 
income.  But  the  object  of  the  union,  from  the  collective 
point  of  view,  is  to  prevent  him  from  accepting  employment, 
under  stress^jDiLsta^vatieiV^11"^^  common 

'jurlgmeiiT'of  the  trade,  would  be  injurious  to  its  interests. 
This  has  been  recognised  from  the  earliest  times  as  a  leading 

1  Thus,  the  Rules  and  Regulations  of  the  Operative  Bleachers,  Finishers,  and 
Dyers'  Association  (Bolton,  1891)  provide  (Rule  24),  under  the  head  of  sick  pay, 
only  for  a  case  not  met  by  the  mere  friendly  society.  "  Should  any  member, 
having  his  family  afflicted  with  smallpox  or  other  infectious  disease  and  as  a 
consequence  be  temporarily  discharged  from  following  his  employment,  such 
member  shall  be  entitled  to  the  ordinary  out  of  work  pay.  But  if  such  member 
become  afflicted  himself  his  pay  shall  cease," 

VOL.  I  M 


1 62  Trade  Union  Function 

object  of  Out  of  Work  pay.  Already,  in  1741,  it  was 
remarked  that  the  woolcombers  "  support  one  another, 
insomuch  that  they  are  become  one  society  throughout  the 
kingdom.  And  that  they  may  keep  up  their  price^  to  encourage 
idleness  rather  than  labor,  if  any  one  of  their  club  is  out 
of  work,  they  give  him  a  ticket  and  money  to  seek  for  work 
at  the  next  town  where  a  box-club  is,  where  he  is  also 
subsisted,  suffered  to  live  a  certain  time  with  them,  and  used 
as  before  ;  by  which  means  he  can  travel  the  kingdom  round, 
be  caressed  at  each  club,  and  not  spend  a  farthing  of  his 
own  or  strike  one  stroke  of  work.  This  has  been  imitated 
by  the  weavers  also,  though  not  carried  through  the  kingdom, 
but  confined  to  the  places  where  they  work."  1 

We  find  the  economic  result  of  this  tramping  system 
exercising  the  minds  of  the  Assistant  Poor  Law  Commissioners 
of  1834.  A  leatherdresser  "belongs  to  an  incorporated  or 
combined  trade  ;  the  directors  of  this  Combination  issue 
tickets  to  the  members.  These  tickets  are  renewed  from 
time  to  time.  The  holder  of  one  goes  from  place  to  place, 
but  must  not  take  the  same  road  more  than  once  in  six 
months.  With  these  intervals  he  is  again  and  again 
assisted.  .  .  .  This  ticket  is  available  in  every  part  of  the 
United  Kingdom  where  a  club  or  lodge  of  the  trade  is 
established.  The  individual  in  question  might  have  had 
work  at  ^i  per  week,  but  he  refused  to  take  it,  or  indeed 
3<DS.  per  week  ;  nothing  under  £2  would  satisfy  him  ;  and 
when  pressed  for  reasons  to  account  for  his  refusing  such 
offers — when  asked  whether  it  would  not  be  better  to  get 
£i  per  week  than  to  trust  to  casual  sources  of  support,  he 

1  A  Short  Essay  upon  Trade  in  General,  by  a  Lover  of  his  Country  (London, 
1741),  quoted  in  the  History  of  the  Worsted  Manufacture  in  England,  by  John 
James  (London,  1857).  How  the  employers  felt  the  independence  thus  given  to 
the  workers  may  be  inferred  from  the  following  advertisement  in  the  Leicester 
Herald,  of  June  1792:— "To  Master  Woolcombers.  The  Journeymen  Wool- 
combers  in  Kendal  have  left  their  work,  and  illegally  combined  to  raise  their  wages 
which  are  already  equal  to  what  is  paid  to  the  Trade  in  any  part  of  the  Kingdom  : 
they  have  also  granted  blanks,  or  certificates,  to  E.  Hewitson,  apprentice  to  Mr. 
Pooley ;  T.  Parkinson,  to  Mr.  Barton  ;  and  W.  Wilkinson,  to  Mr.  Strutt,  who 
without  such  blanks  or  certificates  must  have  remained  with  their  masters," 


The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance  163 

replied  that  he  should  not  like  to  be  *  turned  black '  (query — 
'  returned  black  ')  which  would  be  the  case  if  he  worked  under 
price."1 

Gradually  the  Trade  Unions  themselves  make  clear  the 
real  object  of  this  system  of  mutual  insurance.  In  1844 
the  Spring  Knife  Grinders'  Protection  Society  of  Sheffield 
declare  that  the  "  object  to  be  accomplished  is  to  grant  relief 
to  all  its  members  that  are  out  of  work  ;  that  none  may 
have  the  painful  necessity  of  applying  for  relief  from  the 
parish,  or  comply  with  the  unreasonable  demands  of  our 
employers  or  their  servants? 2  The  Flint  Glass  Makers 
express  the  same  idea.  "  Our  wages  depend  on  the  supply 
of  labor  in  the  market ;  our  interest  is  therefore  to  restrict 
that  supply,  reduce  the  surplus,  make  our  unemployed  com- 
fortable^ without  fear  for  the  morrow — accomplish  this>  and  we 
have  a  command  over  the  surplus  of  our  labor,  and  we  need 
fear  no  unjust  employer?*  Four  years  later  the  Delegate 
Meeting  of  the  Amalgamated  Engineers  resolved  to  extend 
by  nine  weeks  the  period  during  which  a  member  was  allowed 
to  receive  continuously  the  Out  of  Work  allowance.  It  was 
successfully  argued  that  "when  bad  trade  did  arrive  ...  it 
brought  with  it  the  absolute  necessity  of  a  continuous  dona- 
tion ;  for  men,  who  were  unemployed  for  so  long  a  time  as 
to  run  through  their  donation  altogether,  would  be  compelled 
either  to  seek  parish  relief,  or  take  situations  on  terms  injurious 
to  the  trade.  In  the  event  of  their  doing  the  latter,  the 
Society  would  exercise  but  little  control  over  them  if  it 
did  not  entitle  them  to  some  benefit.  For  the  protection  of 
the  trade,  then,  it  was  stated  to  be  absolutely  necessary  to  make 
the  donation  continuous,  so  that  the  members  of  the  Society 
should  be  able  to  resist  the  inducement  of  acting  contrary  to 
the  general  rules  of  a  District?  4  Finally,  we  may  cite  the 

1  Report  of  Poor  Law  Commission  of  1834  ;  Appendix,  p.  900  a. 

2  Manuscript  Rules  of  the  Spring  Knife  Grinders'  Protection  Society  of  Sheffield 
in  old  account  book,  dated  1844. 

3  Flint  Glass  Makers'  Magazine •,  opening  editorial,  No.  I,  Sept.  1850. 

4  Minutes  of  the  Second  Delegate  Meeting  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Engineers^  p.  38  (London,  1854).    The  Constitution  and  Rules  qf  the  Associated 


164  Trade  Union  Function 

case  of  the  Associated  Shipwrights'  Society,  which  has  only 
within  recent  years  systematically  adopted  regular  Out  of 
Work  payments.  The  argument,  used  by  the  general 
secretary  at  the  Delegate  Meeting  in  1885,  which  finally 
decided  the  matter,  was  as  follows  :  "  It  is  utterly  impossible," 
Mr.  Wilkie  told  his  members,  "to  secure  trade  protection 
when  a  third  or  a  half  of  your  trade  are  walking  about  idle 
and  starving.  And  unless  members  of  the  trade  were  pre- 
pared to  buy  up,  more  or  less,  its  surplus  labor  in  the  market, 
it  never  could  have  the  actual  trade  protection  desired." * 

This  historical  explanation  of  the  underlying  object  of 
the  Out  of  Work  benefit  is  borne  out  by  the  actual  practice 
of  to-day.  Whilst  all  the  members  of  a  Trade  Union  are 
enjoined  to  do  their  utmost  to  find  situations  for  their  unem- 
ployed brethren,  and  whilst  these  are  forbidden,  under  severe 
penalty,  to  "refuse  work  when  offered,"  yet  this  is  always 
subject  to  a  fundamental  condition,  so  obvious  to  the  Trade 
Union  mind  as  to  need  no  explicit  statement  in  the  rules. 
A  member  is  not  only  permitted  to  refuse  job  after  job 
if  these  are  offered  to  him  below  the  "  Standard  Rate "  of 
remuneration,  or  otherwise  in  contravention  of  the  normal 
terms  :  he  is  absolutely  forbidden  to  accept  work  on  any 
but  the  conditions  satisfactory  to  his  branch.  The  visitor 
at  a  branch  meeting  of  the  Engineers  or  Carpenters  will 
hear  members,  in  receipt  of  Out  of  Work  pay,  report  to  the 
branch  that  they  have  been  offered  situations  on  such  and 
such  terms,  and  ask  whether  it  is  considered  right  that  they 
should  accept  them.  The  branch  will  discuss  the  question 

Ironmoulders  of  Scotland  (Glasgow,  1892)  explicitly  recognise  the  use  of  the 
Out  of  Work  Benefit  as  a  means  of  maintaining  their  standard  of  wages.  "  Any 
member  leaving  for  want  of  work  .  .  .  shall  be  paid  idle  benefit  .  .  .  but, 
if  leaving  on  own  accord,  he  shall  have  no  claim  to  benefit.  The  phrase 
'  want  of  work '  shall  refer  to  all  kinds  of  dismissal  without  fault  of  the  member 
— slackness,  underpayment,  resisting  a  reduction  of  wages,  or  unjustifiable  abuse  or 
ill-treatment  from  employer  or  foreman.  .  .  .  '  Own  accord '  shall  mean  all  kinds 
of  dismissal  for  irregularity,  absence  without  leave  except  from  illness,  in- 
sobriety, and  captious  or  voluntary  dismissal."  (Rule  30,  sec.  4.) 

1  Address  of  General  Secretary  at  Delegate  Meeting  of  Associated  Shipwrights' 
Society,  1885. 


The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance  165 

from  the  point  of  view  of  the  probable  effect  on  the  Standard 
Rate  ;  and  whilst  they  may  permit  a  maimed  or  aged  member 
to  accept  five  shillings  a  week  less  than  the  normal  wage  of 
the  district,  they  will  prefer  to  keep  a  fully  competent  and 
able-bodied  man  "on  donation,"  rather  than  sanction  any 
departure  from  the  Common  Rule.1 

Here  we  are  outside  the  domain  of  actuarial  science. 
Even  if  it  should  prove  possible  to  reduce  to  an  arithmetical 
scale  of  contributions  and  benefits  the  loss  of  income  caused 
by  mere  slackness  of  trade,  it  must  always  be  out  of  the  ques- 
tion to  determine  what  rate  of  Out  of  Work  benefit  can  safely 
be  awarded  in  return  for  a  given  subscription,  if  the  accept- 
ance of  employment  depends  on  the  policy  of  the  society 
with  regard  to  its  Standard  Rate.  Such  a  condition  takes 
us  out  of  the  category  of  insurance  as  provisionally  defined 
above.  As  understood  and  administered  by  all  Trade  Unions, 
the  Out  of  Work  benefit  is  not  valued  exclusively,  or  even 
mainly,  for  its  protection  of  the  individual  against  casualties. 
In  the  mind  of  the  thoughtful  or  experienced  Trade  Unionist 
its  most  important  function  is  to  protect  the  Standard  Rate 
of  wages  and  other  normal  conditions  of  employment  from 
being  "eaten  away,"  in  bad  times,  by  the  competition  of 
members  driven  by  necessity  to  accept  the  employers'  terms. 

The  reader  will  now  understand  why  this  Mutual  Insur- 
ance must  be  regarded,  not  as  the  end  or  object,  but  as  one 
of  the  Methods  of  Trade  Unionism.  At  first  sight  nothing 
could  appear  more  simple  than  the  mutual  provision  of 
support  in  order  to  enable  a  man  to  seek  work  elsewhere, 
and  not  be  under  an  absolute  compulsion  to  accept  whatever 
terms  an  employer  may  offer.  In  its  economic  effect  upon 
the  labor  market  it  seems  no  more  than  would  result  from 
the  existence  of  individual  savings  in  a  savings  bank.  But 

1  The  Rules  to  be  observed  by  the  members  of  the  Bury  and  District  Tape- 
sizers'  Friendly  Protective  Society  (Bury,  1888)  provide  (p.  7)  that  "if  any  member 
who  is  out  of  work  and  receiving  pay  make  application  for  a  situation  or  be  sent 
for,  and  he  is  offered  a  less  rate  of  wage  than  he  has  been  paid  before,  he  shall 
be  at  liberty  to  take  it  or  not,  and  if  he  refuse  to  take  it  he  shall  not  have  his  pay 
stopped." 


1 66  Trade  Union  Function 

Trade  Unions,  as  Fleeming  Jenkin  pointed  out,  are  far  more 
potent  in  this  respect  than  any  savings  bank,  "  because  they 
enable  the  community  of  workmen  to  acquire  wealth.  .  .  . 
The  individual  workman  knows  that  his  reserve  fund  will  be 
nearly  useless  unless  his  neighbour  has  a  reserve  fund  also. 
If  each  workman  in  a  strike  trusted  to  his  own  funds  only, 
the  poorer  ones  must  give  in  first ;  and  these  would  secure 
work,  while  the  richer,  after  spending  a  part  of  their  reserve, 
would  find  themselves  supplanted  by  the  poorer  competitors, 
and  the  sacrifice  made  uselessly.  A  combined  reserve  fund 
gives  great  power  by  insuring  that  all  suffer  alike.  The 
Trade  Union,  therefore,  has  a  permanent  action  in  raising 
wages,  because  it  enables  men  to  accumulate  a  common 
fund,  with  which  they  can  sustain  their  resolution  not  to  work 
unless  they  obtain  such  pay  as  will  give  increased  comfort." l 
If  this  collective  reserve  fund  coexists  with  a  common 
understanding  as  to  the  terms  without  which  no  member 
will  accept  employment,  it  is  obvious  that  we  have  a  deliberate 
and  conscious  use  of  Mutual  Insurance,  not  to  relieve  indi- 
vidual distress,  but  to  enforce  a  Trade  Union  Regulation. 

The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance  is  pursued,  more  or 
less  consciously,  by  every  union  that  gives  benefits  at  all. 
Until  Collective  Bargaining  was  permitted  by  the  employers, 
and  before  Legal  Enactment  was  within  the  workmen's  reach, 
Mutual  Insurance  was  the  only  method  by  which  Trade 
Unionists  could  lawfully  attain  their  end.  Hence  its  high 
favor  with  the  group  of  astute  officials  who  led  the  work- 
men between  1845  an^  l$7$-  Dunning,  in  fact,  expressly 
gives  it  as  the  main  method  of  Trade  Unionism.  "  Singly 
the  employer  can  stand  out  longer  in  the  bargain  than  the 
journeyman  ;  and  as  he  who  can  stand  out  longest  in  the 
bargain  will  be  sure  to  command  his  own  terms,  the  work- 
men combine  to  put  themselves  on  something  like  an  equality 
in  the  bargain  for  the  sale  of  their  labor  with  their  employer. 
This  is  the  rationale  of  trade  societies.  .  .  .  The  object  in- 

1  "  Graphic  Representation  of  the  Laws  of  Supply  and  Demand,"  by  Fleeming 
Jenkin,  in  Recess  Studies  (Edinburgh,  1870),  pp.  183-4. 


The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance  1 6  7 

tended  is  carried  out  by  providing  a  fund  for  the  support  of 
its  members  when  out  of  employ,  for  a  certain  number  of 
weeks  in  the  year.  This  is  the  usual  and  regular  way  in 
which  the  labor  of  the  members  of  a  trade  society  is  protected, 
that  the  man's  present  necessities  may  not  compel  him  to 
take  less  than  the  wages  which  the  demand  and  supply  of 
labor  in  the  trade  have  previously  adjusted."1 

The  same  view  was  expressed  by  William  Allan,  the 
first  secretary  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers. 
"  We  are  very  little  engaged  in  regulating  "  rates  of  wages,  he 
told  the  Royal  Commission  in  1867,  "they  regulate  them- 
selves, if  I  may  use  the  expression.  If  a  member  believed," 
he  continued,  "that  he  was  not  getting  a  proper  rate  of 
wages,  the  society  would  encourage  him  in  objecting,  that  is 
to  say,  would  pay  him  his  benefit  while  out  of  employment. 
.  .  .  The  man  would  go  to  the  branch  to  which  he  belonged, 
and  would  there  state  that  he  was  only  receiving  a  certain 
rate  of  wages  ;  if  he  wished  to  leave  his  employment  he 
would  ask  the  question  whether  under  the  circumstances  he 
would  be  entitled  to  what  we  call  donation,  that  is  Out  of 
Work  Benefit,  if  he  left  the  situation  ;  and  in  all  probability 
the  society  would  say,  you  can  leave  and  we  will  pay  you 
the  benefit.  Or  they  might  say,  we  believe  you  are  getting 
as  much  as  you  ought  to  expect."  2 

In  some  small  and  highly  organised  trades  of  skilled 
handicraftsmen,  this  method  of  enforcing  Trade  Union 
regulations  by  Mutual  Insurance  has  tacitly  elaborated  into 
an  effective  weapon,  not  only  of  defence,  but  also  of  aggres- 
sion. We  may  instance  the  Spanish  and  Morocco  Leather 
Finishers'  Society,  a  small  but  powerful  union,  practically 
co-extensive  with  the  craft,  which  has  not  for  fifty  years 

1  T.  J.  Dunning,  Trades  Unions  and  Strikes :  their  Philosophy  and  Intention 
(London,  1860),  p.  10.     See  also  Dunning's  articles  on  "  Wages  of  Labour  and 
Trade  Societies,"  in  the  second,  third,  and  fourth  numbers  of  the  Bookbinders' 
Trade  Circular  (1851) ;  History  of  Trade   Unionism,  p.  179. 

2  First  Report  of  the  Commissioners  appointed  to  enquire  into  the  Organisation 
and  Rules  of  Trades  Unions  and  other  Associations  (London,  1867).     Evidence  of 
W.  Allan,  Questions  787-789. 


1 68  Trade  Union  Function 

ordered  a  formal  strike,  or  in  any  way  overtly  "  intervened 
between  employer  and  employed."  Nevertheless,  it  has 
known  how  to  enforce  a  detailed  uniform  price-list  in  every 
centre,  new  or  old,  in  which  the  trade  is  carried  on  ;  it  has 
maintained  this  piece-work  list  practically  unaltered  for  fifty 
years,  notwithstanding  many  improvements  in  processes  ;  it 
has,  consequently,  kept  up  its  members'  earnings  to  certainly 
more  than  £2  per  week  ;  and  it  has  successfully  enforced  a 
rigid  limitation  of  apprentices,  there  being  nowhere  more 
than  one  to  seven  journeymen.  Yet  no  overt  collective 
movement  is  ever  made.  If  any  employer  refuses  to  conform 
to  the  regulations,  even  in  the  slightest  degree,  the  members 
leave  him  one  by  one,  and  receive  Out  of  Work  benefit,  which 
may  continue  for  thirty-nine  weeks.1  It  is  usually  found,  we 
are  told,  that  an  employer  remedies  any  grievance  after  he 
has  had  to  put  up  with  a  new  man  every  week  or  two  for  a 
few  months.  In  1845  tne  Old  Smiths'  Society,  which  had 
suffered  severely  between  1827  and  1844  from  numerous 
small  strikes,  removed  from  their  rules  all  provision  for  these 
pitched  battles  with  their  employers,  in  favor  of  this  more 
silent  form  of  pressure.  The  preamble  to  the  rules,  drawn  up 
by  the  Delegate  Meeting  of  1845,  adds,  "Disputes  .  .  .  can 
only  be  settled  by  friendly  consultations  between  both  master 
and  man,  imbued  with  the  spirit  of  mutually  imparting  facts, 
with  a  view  to  render  assistance  to  each  other  ;  if  this,  in  con- 
nection with  the  efforts  of  mutual  and  disinterested  friends, 
cannot  be  accomplished,  we  say  then  let  men  and  masters 
part ;  offer  no  opposition  ;  the  men,  however  great  or  small 
their  number,  to  be  supplied  with  means  of  existence  until 
they  obtain  other  situations  of  work  from  the  funds  of  the 
society  ;  and  the  employers  to  obtain  other  men  as  best  they 
may  ;  and  we  contend  that  this  unassuming  quiet  plan  of 
operations  is,  according  to  its  number  of  members,  accom- 
plishing, and  will  continue  to  accomplish,  infinitely  more  real 
good  to  the  trade  in  all  its  ramifications,  at  a  minimum 

1  Rules  to  be  observed  by  the  Members  of  the  Leeds  Friendly  Society  of  Spanish 
and  Morocco  Leather  Finishers  (Leeds,  1879). 


The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance  1 69 

expense  to  its  members,  than  any  other  plan  of  operation  by 
any  other  society."  *  The  same  position  was  aimed  at  by 
the  Flint  Glass  Makers  in  1850,  when  their  magazine  was 
advocating  the  use  of  this  nameless  weapon  which  we  have 
christened,  for  our  own  convenience,  the  "  Strike  in  Detail." 
"  As  man  after  man  leaves,  .  .  .  then  it  is  that  the  proud 
and  haughty  spirit  of  the  oppressor  is  brought  down,  and  he 
feels  the  power  he  cannot  see."  2 

This  application  of  mutual  insurance  may  be  made  the 
method  of  enforcing  any  Common  Rule  whatsoever ;  and  a 
very  effective  instrument  it  is.  An  employer  whose  workmen 
leave  him  one  by  one,  after  due  notice,  may  find  little  diffi- 
culty in  filling  their  places.  But  if  the  new-comers,  after  a 
brief  stay,  one  by  one  give  notice  that  they,  too,  will  leave, 
he  is  placed  in  a  serious  difficulty.  He  cannot  close  his 
doors  and  appeal  for  support  to  his  fellow-employers,  as 
there  is  no  strike,  and  no  refusal  on  the  part  of  the  Trade 
Unionists  to  accept  his  terms.  Nevertheless,  his  constant 
inability  to  retain  any  workman  for  more  than  a  week  or 
two,  may  easily  become  so  harassing  that  he  will  be  forced 
to  inquire  carefully  in  what  respect  his  employment  falls 
below  the  standard  of  the  trade,  and  to  conform  to  it.  The 
Trade  Union,  on  the  other  hand,  runs  no  risk  of  retaliation, 
and,  as  only  a  few  men  are  on  the  books  at  any  one  time, 
incurs  the  minimum  of  expense.  As  a  deliberate  Trade 
Union  policy,  the  Strike  in  Detail  depends  upon  the  extent 
to  which  the  union  has  secured  the  adhesion  of  all  the  com- 
petent men  in  the  trade,  and  upon  their  capacity  for 
persistent  and  self-restrained  pursuit  of  a  common  end.  It 
could,  accordingly,  never  become  the  sole  method  of  any  but 
a  small,  wealthy,  and  closely  knit  society  ;  but  in  such  a 
society  it  may  easily,  in  its  coercive  effect  on  the  employer, 
surpass  even  an  Act  of  Parliament  itself. 

1  Report  on  Trade  Societies'  Rules  by  Mr.   (now  the  Rt.  Hon.)  G.  Shaw 
Lefevre  in  Social  Science  Association's  Report  on   Trades  Societies  and  Strikes 
(London,  1860). 

2  Flint  Glass  Makers'  Magazine,  July  1850. 


170  Trade  Union  Function 

The  Strike  in  Detail  is  only  a  more  deliberate  and 
self-conscious  application  of  the  method  of  maintaining  the 
standard  of  life  by  Mutual  Insurance  customary  among  all 
Trade  Unionists.  It  is  impossible  to  draw  any  logical  dis- 
tinction between  the  action  of  the  little  union  of  Leather 
Finishers  and  that  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers, 
as  explained  by  William  Allan  and  T.  J.  Dunning,  or  indeed 
any  union  which  maintains  a  member  in  idleness  rather  than 
allow  him  to  accept  work  "  contrary  to  the  interests  of  the 
trade."  The  persistent  adhesion  of  Trade  Unionists  to  the 
Out  of  Work  benefit,  and  their  secondary  adoption  of  what 
we  have  called  the  friendly  society  business,  appear  as  a 
perfectly  consistent,  homogeneous  policy  the  moment  the 
true  Trade  Union  point  of  view  is  caught.  Any  provision 
which  secures  the  members  of  the  trade  against  destitution 
prevents  an  employer  taking  advantage  of  their  necessities.1 
Not  Out  of  Work  benefit  alone,  but  also  sick  pay,  grants  to 
replace  tools  or  property  lost  or  burnt,  burial  money  for  wife 
or  child,  and  especially  accident  benefit  and  superannuation 
allowance,  all  serve  to  enforce  the  claim  of  the  workman  "  to 
be  dealt  with  as  an  intelligent  being,  and  not  merely  as  a 
bale  of  goods  or  article  of  merchandise.  This,"  emphatically 
declares  the  Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders,  "  is,  then,  the 
main  and  central  pillar  of  our  organisation.  Around  it  are 
clustered  those  monetary  benefits  that  are  stated  above,  and 
it  is  from  this  grand  standpoint  those  benefits  must  all  be 
estimated  :  for  from  this  point  only  it  is  at  all  possible  to 
come  to  a  right  and  fair  conclusion  as  to  their  real  value  to 
individual  members."  2 

1  We  may  cite  a  curious  small  case  among  the  Curriers.      The    London 
journeymen  curriers  have  always  strenuously  resisted  the  employers'  attempts  to 
make  them  take  out  shoe  hides  at  an  average  weight,  instead  of  weighing  each 
one  separately.      In  1854  certain  members  represented  to  the  union  that  their 
employer  had  taken  advantage  of  the  slackness  of  work  in  the  winter  season  to 
try  to  enforce  this  practice  upon  them  ;  and  that  if  the  union  would  make  them 
each  a  loan,  they  could  dispense  with  sending  in  their  bills  to  their  employer  for 
that  week,  which  would  have  a  good  effect  as  demonstrating  their  power  to  stand 
out.     The  union  readily  agreed  to  lend  each  man  a  pound  on  condition  that  he 
drew  no  wages  that  week.     MS.  Minute  Book,  1854. 

2  Preface  to  Rules  to  be  observed  by  the  Members  of  the  Friendly  Society  of 


The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance  171 

Mutual  Insurance,  even  when  considered  purely  as  a 
Method  of  Trade  Unionism,  is  by  no  means  beyond  criticism. 
The  lack  of  legal  or  financial  security  of  the  friendly  benefits 
may  be  worth  tolerating  by  a  wage-earner  for  the  sake  of  the 
trade  as  a  whole ;  but  it  is  none  the  less  an  evil  on  that 
account.  And  even  the  successful  Strike  in  Detail  of  the 
Leather  Finishers  has  grave  drawbacks,  from  its  own  stand- 
point. No  Trade  Unionist  would  deny  that  the  deliber- 
ately concerted  Common  Rules,  to  which  workmen  and 
employers  must  alike  conform,  ought  to  be  framed  after 
consideration,  not  of  the  desires  of  one  class  alone,  but  from 
all  points  of  view.  The  method  of  Mutual  Insurance  leaves 
no  place  for  discussion  with  the  employers.  Each  party 
makes  up  its  own  mind,  relies  on  its  power  of  holding  out, 
and  leaves  the  issue  to  depend  merely  on  secret  endurance. 
Frank  and  full  discussion  might  have  revealed  facts  previously 
unknown,  which  would  have  altered  the  views  of  the  parties. 
It  might  have  been  discovered  that  some  points  most  keenly 
insisted  on  by  one  side  were  regarded  as  unimportant  by  the 
other.  The  influence  of  public  opinion  would  have  moderated 
the  negotiations.  These  tendencies  make,  in  Collective  Bar- 
gaining, for  a  compromise  often  representing  a  real  gain  to 
both  parties.  For  all  this,  the  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance 
allows  no  place.  It  is,  therefore,  not  surprising  to  find  that 
the  most  highly  developed  and  successful  modern  organisa- 
tions make  little  use  of  Mutual  Insurance  as  a  method  of 
industrial  regulation.  Among  the  Coalminers  and  Cotton 
Operatives,  who  together  comprise  a  fifth  of  the  Trade 
Union  world,  friendly  benefits,  and  even  Out  of  Work 
donation,  play  only  the  most  trifling  part.  And  it  is  sig- 
nificant that  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  in  many 

Ironfounders  (London,  1891).  It  is  interesting  to  find  that  this  use  of  Mutual 
Insurance  among  workers  was  elaborately  explained  and  defended  in  1819  by 
the  well-known  Baptist  minister,  the  Reverend  Robert  Hall ;  see  his  pamphlets, 
An  Appeal  to  the  Pttblic  on  the  Subject  of  the  Framework  Knitters'  Fund  (Leicester, 
1819),  and  A  Reply  to  the  Principal  Objections  advanced  by  Cobbett  and  others 
against  the  Framework  Knitters'  Friendly  Relief  Society  (Leicester,  1821),  both 
included  in  his  Works  (London,  1832),  vol.  iii. 


172 


Trade  Union  Function 


respects  the  most  successful  of  the  great  unions,  whilst 
utilising  to  the  full  a  most  elaborate  system  of  Mutual 
Insurance,  keeps  the  provision  against  unavoidable  casualties 
entirely  distinct  from  its  trade  objects.  For  all  that  concerns 
the  maintenance  and  improvement  of  the  conditions  of  em- 
ployment the  Boilermakers,  like  the  Coalminers  and  the 
Cotton  Operatives,  resort  to  one  or  other  of  the  alternative 
Methods  of  Trade  Unionism,  Collective  Bargaining,  or  Legal 
Enactment. 


CHAPTER    II 

THE    METHOD    OF    COLLECTIVE    BARGAINING 

THE  nature  of  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining  will  be 
best  understood  by  a  series  of  examples. 

In  unorganised  trades  the  individual  workman,  applying 
for  a  job,  accepts  or  refuses  the  terms  offered  by  the  employer, 
without  communication  with  his  fellow-workmen,  and  with- 
out any  other  consideration  than  the  exigencies  of  his  own 
position.  For  the  sale  of  his  labor  he  makes,  with  the 
employer,  a  strictly  individual  bargain.1  But  if  a  group  of 
workmen  concert  together,  and  send  representatives  to  con- 
duct the  bargaining  on  behalf  of  the  whole  body,  the  position 
is  at  once  changed.  Instead  of  the  employer  making  a 
series  of  separate  contracts  with  isolated  individuals,  he  meets 
with  a  collective  will,  and  settles,  in  a  single  agreement,  the 
principles  upon  which,  for  the  time  being,  all  workmen  of  a 
particular  group,  or  class,  or  grade,  will  be  engaged.  For 
instance,  in'  a  cabinet-making  shop,  if  a  new  pattern  is 
brought  out,  the  men  in  the  shop  hold  a  brief  and  informal 
meeting  to  discuss  the  price  at  which  it  can  be  executed,  the 

1  The  phrase  "  Individual  Bargaining  "  is  used  incidentally  by  C.  Morrison 
in  his  Essay  on  the  Relations  between  Labour  and  Capital  (London,  1854),  as 
equivalent  to  "what  may  be  called  the  commercial  principle,"  according  to  which 
"  the  workman  endeavours  to  sell  his  labor  as  dearly  and  the  employer  to  pur- 
chase it  as  cheaply  as  possible"  (p.  9). 

We  are  not  aware  of  any  use  of  the  phrase  "Collective  Bargaining"  before 
that  in  The  Cooperative  Movement  in  Great  Britain  (London,  1891),  p.  217,  by 
Beatrice  Potter  (Mrs.  Sidney  Webb),  where  it  is  employed  in  the  present  sense. 


1 74  Trade  Union  Function 

rough  basis  being  whether,  taking  into  account  the  un- 
familiarity  of  the  work,  and  the  nature  of  the  task,  they  can 
make  no  less  net  wages  per  hour  than  they  have  been 
hitherto  earning.  The  foreman  has  meanwhile  been  estimat- 
ing the  job  in  his  own  way,  on  much  the  same  basis  as  the 
men,  but  probably  arriving  at  a  slightly  lower  figure.  The 
men's  representative  talks  the  matter  over  with  the  foreman, 
and  some  compromise  is  come  to,  the  job  standing  at  that 
price  for  the  whole  shop.  This  process  differs  from  that  of 
a  series  of  individual  bargains  with  the  separate  workmen,  in 
that  the  particular  exigencies  of  each  are  ruled  out  of  con- 
sideration. If  the  foreman  had  dealt  privately  with  each 
man,  he  might  have  found  some  in  such  necessity  that  he 
could  have  driven  them  to  take  the  job  practically  at  any 
price  rather  than  be  without  work  for  even  half  a  day. 
Others,  again,  relying  on  exceptional  strength  or  endurance, 
would  have  seen  their  way  to  make  the  standard  earnings  at 
a  piecework  rate  upon  which  the  average  worker  could  not 
even  subsist.  By  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining  the 
foreman  is  prevented  from  taking  advantage  of  the  competi- 
tion of  both  these  classes  of  men  to  beat  down  the  earnings 
of  the  other  workmen.  The  starving  man  gets  his  job  at 
the  same  piecework  rate  as  the  workman  who  could  afford 
to  stand  out  for  his  usual  earnings.  The  superior  crafts- 
man retains  all  his  advantages  over  his  fellows,  but  without 
allowing  his  superiority  to  be  made  the  means  of  reducing 
the  weekly  wage  of  the  ordinary  worker. 

This  example  of  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining  is 
taken  from  the  practice  of  a  "  shop  club  "  in  a  relatively 
unorganised  trade.  The  skilled  artisans  in  the  building 
trades  afford  a  typical  instance  of  the  second  stage.  The 
"  shop  bargain  "  of  such  a  trade  as  the  cabinet-makers  merely 
rules  out  the  exigencies  of  the  particular  workmen  in  a 
single  establishment.  But  this  establishment  is  exposed  to 
the  undercutting  of  other  establishments  in  the  same  town. 
One  employer  might  have  to  give  exceptional  terms  to  his 
"  shop  club "  in  a  sudden  rush  of  urgent  orders,  whilst  the 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining         175 

workmen  in  other  firms  might  be  virtually  at  the  masters' 
mercy  owing  to  bad  trade.  Directly  a  Trade  Union  is 
formed  in  any  town,  an  attempt  is  made  to  exclude  from 
influence  on  the  terms,  the  exigencies  of  particular  employers 
no  less  than  those  of  particular  workmen.  Thus  in  the 
building  trades  we  find  the  unions  of  Carpenters,  Bricklayers, 
Stonemasons,  Plumbers,  Plasterers,  and  sometimes  those  of 
the  Painters,  Slaters,  and  Builders'  Laborers  obtaining  formal 
"  working  rules,"  binding  on  all  the  employers  and  work- 
men of  the  town  or  district.  This  Collective  Bargaining, 
arranged  at  a  conference  between  the  local  master  builders, 
and  the  local  officials  of  the  national  unions,  settles,  for  a 
specified  term,  the  hours  of  beginning  and  ending  work,  the 
minimum  rate  of  wages,  the  payment  for  overtime,  the  age 
and  number  of  apprentices  to  be  taken,  the  arrangements  as 
to  piecework,  the  holidays  to  be  allowed, -the  notice  to  be 
given  by  employers  or  workmen  terminating  engagements, 
the  accommodation  to  be  provided  for  meals  and  the  safe 
custody  of  tools,  and  numerous  allowances  or  extra  payments 
for  travelling,  lodging,  "walking  time,"  "grinding  money," 
etc.  These  elaborate  codes,  unalterable  except  by  formal 
notice  from  the  organisations  on  either  side,  thus  place  on  a 
uniform  footing  as  regards  the  hiring  of  labor  the  wealthiest 
contractor  and  the  builder  on  the  brink  of  bankruptcy,  the 
firm  crowded  with  orders  and  that  standing  practically  idle. 
On  the  other  hand,  the  superior  workman  retains  his  freedom 
to  exact  higher  rates  for  his  special  work,  whilst  the  employer 
of  superior  business  ability,  or  technical  knowledge,  and  the  firm 
enjoying  the  best  machinery  or  plant,  preserve,  it  is  claimed, 
every  fraction  of  their  advantage  over  their  competitors.1 

1  The  number  of  these  "  working  rules "  in  force  in  the  United  Kingdom 
has  never  been  ascertained,  but  it  must  be  very  large,  there  being  scarcely  any 
town  in  which  one  or  other  of  the  building  trades  has  not  obtained  a  formal 
treaty  with  its  employers.  Our  own  collection  of  these  treaties,  in  the  building 
trades  alone,  numbers  several  hundreds.  Specimens  will  be  found  in  the  Labour 
Gazette  of  the  Board  of  Trade  for  November  1894 ;  and  in  Le  Trade  Unionisme 
en  Angleterre,  edited  by  Paul  de  Rousiers  (Paris,  1897),  pp.  68-70.  The  British 
Library  of  Political  Science,  10  Adelphi  Terrace,  London,  contains  these  and 
other  Trade  Union  documents. 


176  Trade  Union  Function 

The  building  trades,  in  which  one  town  does  not 
obviously  compete  with  another,  have  hitherto  stopped  at 
this  stage  of  Collective  Bargaining.  Where  the  product  of 
different  towns  goes  to  the  same  market,  we  see,  in  the  best 
organised  industries,  a  still  further  development.  The  great 
staple  trades  of  cotton-spinning  and  cotton-weaving  have 
ruled  out,  not  merely  the  exigencies  of  particular  workmen 
in  one  mill,  or  of  particular  mills  in  one  town,  but  also  those 
of  the  various  towns  over  which  the  industries  have  spread. 
The  general  level  of  wages  in  all  the  cotton-spinning  towns 
is,  for  instance,  settled  by  the  national  agreements  between 
the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners 
and  the  Master  Cotton-spinners'  Association.  No  employer, 
and  no  group  of  workmen,  no  district  association  of  em- 
ployers, and  no  "  province  "  of  the  Trade  Union,  can  propose 
an  advance  or  accept  a  special  reduction  from  the  estab- 
lished level  of  earnings.  General  advances  or  reductions  are 
negotiated  at  long  intervals,  and  with  great  deliberateness, 
between  the  national  representatives  of  each  party.  Thus 
we  see  ruled  out,  not  merely  all  personal  or  local  exigencies, 
but  also  the  temporary  gluts  or  contractions  of  the  market, 
whether  in  the  raw  material  or  in  the  product.  All  firms 
in  a  district,  and  all  districts  in  the  industry  being,  as  far  as 
possible,  placed  upon  an  identical  footing  as  to  the  rate  at 
which  they  obtain  human  labor,  their  competition  takes,  it  is 
contended,  the  form  of  improving  the  machinery,  getting  the 
best  and  cheapest  raw  material,  and  obtaining  the  most 
advantageous  market  for  their  wares. 

A  similar  series  of  collective  agreements  exists  in  some 
other  industries.  Among  the  iron-shipbuilders,  for  instance, 
a  gang  of  platers  will  bargain,  through  their  first  hand,  as  to 
the  exact  terms  upon  which  they  will  undertake  a  job  in  the 
building  of  an  iron  ship.  But  the  foreman  cannot  offer,  or 
the  men  accept  terms  which  in  any  way  conflict  with  the 
"  district  by-laws  " — a  detailed  code  regulating  hours,  over- 
time, extra  allowances,  and  often  also  the  piecework  rates 
for  ordinary  work,  formally  agreed  to  by  the  district  com- 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          177 

mittee  of  the  Trade  Union  and  the  local  association  of 
employers.  Moreover,  the  district  by-laws,  unalterable  for 
a  fixed  term,  exclude  the  influence  of  any  sudden  glut  or 
famine  in  the  labor  market,  or  any  temporary  fluctuation  of 
the  trade  of  the  port.  But  this  is  not  all.  The  district 
by-laws  are  themselves  subject  to  the  formal  treaties  on  such 
matters  as  apprenticeship  and  the  standard  level  of  wages 
concluded  between  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers  and 
Iron-shipbuilders  and  the  Employers'  Federation  of  Ship- 
building and  Engineering  Trades.  These  treaties,  settling 
certain  questions  for  the  whole  kingdom,  rule  out  on  those 
points  the  exigencies  of  particular  localities,  and  place  all 
ports  upon  an  equality.  Thus  the  collective  bargain  made 
by  the  group  of  platers  on  a  particular  job  in  one  establish- 
ment of  a  certain  town  imports  a  hierarchy  of  other  collective 
bargains,  concluded  by  the  representatives  of  the  contracting 
parties  in  their  gradually  widening  spheres  of  action. 

This  practice  of  Collective  Bargaining  has,  in  one  form 
or  another,  superseded  the  old  individual  contract  between 
master  and  servant  over  a  very  large  proportion  of  the 
industrial  field.  "  I  will  pay  each  workman  according  to 
his  necessity  or  merit,  and  deal  with  no  one  but  my  own 
hands," — once  the  almost  universal  answer  of  employers — 
is  now  seldom  heard  in  any  important  industry,  except  in 
out-of-the-way  districts,  or  from  exceptionally  arbitrary 
masters.1  But  it  is  interesting  to  notice  that  Collective 
Bargaining  is  neither  co- extensive  with,  nor  limited  to, 
Trade  Union  organisation.  A  few  old -standing  wealthy 
unions  of  restricted  membership  have  sometimes  preferred, 
as  we  saw  in  the  last  chapter,  to  attain  their  ends  by  the 
Method  of  Mutual  Insurance,  whilst  others,  at  all  periods, 
have  been  formed  with  the  express  design  of  attaining  their 
ends  by  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment.  On  the  other 

1  Mr.  Lecky  observes  (Democracy  and  Liberty,  vol.  ii.  p.  361)  that  collective 
agreements  "are  becoming,  much  more  than  engagements  between  individual 
employers  and  individual  workmen,  the  form  into  which  English  industry  is 
manifestly  developing. " 

VOL.1  N 


1 78  Trade  Union  Function 

hand,  whole  sections  of  the  wage-earning  class,  not  included 
in  any  Trade  Union,  habitually  have  their  rate  of  wages  and 
often  some  other  conditions  of  their  employment  settled  by 
Collective  Bargaining.  We  do  not  here  refer  merely  to  such 
cases  as  the  "  shop-bargain,"  which  we  have  just  described. 
The  historic  strikes  of  the  London  building  trades  in  1859, 
and  the  Newcastle  engineers  in  1871,  were  both  conducted 
by  committees  elected  at  mass  meetings  of  members  of  the 
trade,  among  whom  the  Trade  Unionists  formed  an  insig- 
nificant minority.1  In  the  history  of  the  building  and 
engineering  trades  there  are  numerous  instances  of  agree- 
ments being  concluded,  on  behalf  of  a  whole  district,  by 
temporary  committees  of  non  -  unionists,  and  where  the 
Trade  Unions  themselves  initiate  and  conduct  the  negotia- 
tions the  agreements  arrived  at  habitually  govern  in  these 
industries,  not  the  members  alone,  but  the  great  bulk  of 
similar  workmen  in  the  district.  Here  and  there  an 
eccentric  employer  may  choose  to  depart  from  the  regular 
terms,  but  the  great  majority  find  it  more  convenient  to 
comply  with  what  becomes,  in  fact,  the  "  custom  of  the 
trade."  So  thoroughly  has  the  Collective  Bargaining  been 
recognised  in  the  building  trades,  that  county  court  judges 
now  usually  hold  that  the  "  working  rules "  of  the  district 
are  implied  as  part  of  the  wage -contract,  if  no  express 
stipulation  has  been  made  on  the  points  therein  dealt  with. 
Collective  Bargaining  thus  extends  over  a  much  larger 
part  of  the  industrial  field  than  Trade  Unionism.  Precise 
statistics  do  not  exist,  but  our  impression^js__that».  in  all 
skilled  trades,  where  men  work  in  concert,  on  the  employers' 
premises,  ninety  per  cent  of  the  workmen  find,  either  their 
rate  of  wages  or  their  hours  of  work,  and  often  many  other 
details,  predetermined  by  a  collective  bargain  in  which  they 
personally  have  taken  no  part,  but  in  which  their  interests 
Have  beerTdealt  with  by  representatives  of  their  class. 

But  though  Collective  Bargaining  prevails  over  a  much 
larger  area  than   Trade   Unionism,  it  is  the   Trade   Union 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  210,  299  ;  compare  pp.  302,  305. 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          1 79 

alone  which  can  provide  the  machinery  for  any  but  its  most 
casual  and  limited  application.  Without  a  Trade  Union 
in  the  industry,  it  would  be  almost  impossible  to  get  a 
Common  Rule  extending  over  a  whole  district,  and  hopeless 
to  attempt  a  national  agreement.  If  therefore  the  collective 
bargain  aims  at  excluding  from  influence  on  the  bargain,  the 
exigencies  of  particular  firms  or  particular  districts,  and  not 
merely  those  of  particular  workmen  in  a  single  establishment, 
Trade  Union  organisation  is  indispensable.  Moreover,  it  is 
the  Trade  Union  alone  which  can  supply  the  machinery  for 
the  automatic  interpretation  and  the  peaceful  revision  of  the 
general  agreement.  To  Collective  Bargaining,  the  machinery 
of  Trade  Unionism  may  bring,  in  fact,  both  continuity  and 
elasticity. 

The  development  of  a  definite  and  differentiated 
machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining  in  the  Trade  Union 
world  coincides,  as  might  be  expected,  with  its  enlargement 
from  the  workshop  to  the  whole  town,  and  from  the  town  to 
the  whole  industry.  As  soon  as  a  Trade  Union  properly  so 
called  comes  into  existence  with  a  president  and  secretary, 
it  becomes  more  and  more  usual  for  these  officers  to  act  as 
the  workmen's  representatives  in  trade  negotiations.  This  is 
the  stage  in  which  we  find  nearly  all  the  single-branched 
unions,  such  as  those  of  the  Sheffield  trades,  the  Dublin 
local  societies,  the  Coopers,  Sailmakers,  and  other  small  and 
compact  bodies  of  workmen  all  over  the  kingdom.  Even 
where  the  growth  of  a  local  union  into  a  national  society 
has  necessitated  the  appointment  of  a  salaried  general 
secretary,  giving  his  whole  time  to  his  duties,  it  is  exceptional 
to  find  him  conducting  all,  or  even  the  bulk  of  the  negotia- 
tions of  its  members  with  their  employers.  In  the  United 
Operative  Plumbers'  Association,  for  instance,  practically  the 
whole  of  the  Collective  Bargaining  is  still  conducted  by  the 
branch  officials,  or  by  representative  workmen  specially  selected 
as  delegates.  A  further  stage  is  marked  by  the  creation  of 
permanent  committees,  unconcerned  with  the  ordinary  branch 
administration,  to  deal  solely  with  local  trade  questions. 


1 80  Trade  Union  Function 

Thus  the  bulk  of  the  Collective  Bargaining  of  the  members 
of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  was,  until  1892, 
conducted  by  the  society's  district  committees,  each  acting 
for  the  whole  of  a  local  industrial  district,  in  which  there 
-e  often  many  branches.  These  negotiators  are,  like  the 
>ranch  officials,  men  working  at  their  trade,  and  only  spas- 
todically  engaged  in  special  business  of  industrial  nego- 
tiation. Even  disputes  of  such  national  importance  as  the 
costly  and  disastrous  strikes  of  the  Tyneside  engineers  of 
1891,  were  initiated  and  managed  by  the  local  district 
committees  and  their  officials,  that  is  to  say,  by  workmen 
called  from  the  workshop  only  for  the  time  required  by  the 
society's  business.  Over  more  than  one-third  of  the  Trade 
Union  world,  including  such  old  established  and  widely 
extended  unions  as  the  Friendly  Society  of  Operative  Stone- 
masons, the  Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders,  and  the 
Operative  Bricklayers'  Society,  the  workmen  have  not 
developed  ^an^_jnpj^L_s^eidajisedmachinery  for  Collective 
Bargaining  than  the  branch  or^onsWct--ee{»ffi4ttee  of  men 
working  at  their  trade,  meeting  representative  employers 
when  occasion  arises.  This  primitive  machinery,  although  a 
great  advance  on  the  "  shop-club,"  has  manifest  disadvantages. 
If,  as  often  happens,  a  personal  quarrel  or  local  bitterness  is 
at  the  bottom  of  the  dispute,  the  prominent  local  workman 
who  represents  his  fellows  can  hardly  escape  its  influence. 
And,  apart  from  personal  antagonisms  and  questions  of 
temper,  the  fact  that  it  is  the  conditions  of  his  own  life  that 
are  involved  does  not  conduce  to  that  combination  of 
courage  and  reasonableness  most  likely  to  lead  to  a  lasting 
settlement.  If  the  negotiator  himself  is  fortunately  placed, 
or  would  personally  be  much  injured  by  a  strike,  he  will 
be  tempted  to  acquiesce  in  conditions  not  advantageous  to 
the  whole  trade.  In  the  reverse  case — perhaps  the  more 
common — the  energetic  and  active-minded  workman,  whom 
his  fellows  choose  to  represent  them,  is  apt  to  find,  in  the 
joy  of  the  fight,  a  relief  from  the  monotony  of  manual 
labor.  If  a  strike  ensues,  it  brings  to  him  at  any  rate  the 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          1 8 1 

compensation  that  for  a  few  weeks,  or  perhaps  months, 
he  becomes  the  paid  organise1r~6F"the^mie¥VJQyerwhelrned, 
it  is  true,  with  anxious  and  harassing  work,  but  temporarily 
exchanging  a  position  of  passive  obedience  for  one  of  active 
leadership. 

But,  apart  altogether  from  the  disturbing  influence  of  the 
"  personaf  equation,"  it  is  obvious  that  the  manual  workers 
will  stand  at  a  grave  disadvantage  if  they  do  not  command 
the  services  of  an  expert  negotiator.  Unfortunately  for  his 
interests,  the  workman  has  an  inveterate  belief  in  what  he 
calls  a  "  practical  man  " — that  is,  one  who  is  actually  working 
at  the  trade  concerned.  He  does  not  see  that  negotiation 
is  in  itself  a  craft,  in  which  a  man  must  have  had  a  special 
training  before  he  can  be  considered  a  "  practical  "  man  for 
the  business  in  hand.  The  proper  adjustment  of  the  rate 
of  remuneration  in  a  given  establishment  requires,  to  begin 
with,  a  wide  range  of  industrial  and  economic  knowledge. 
Unless  the  workman's  negotiator  is  accurately  acquainted 
with  the  rates  and  precise  conditions  prevailing  in  other 
establishments  and  in  other  districts,  he  will  be  unable  to 
criticise  the  statements  which  will  be  made  by  the  employer, 
and  incapable  of  advising  his  own  clients  whether  their 
demand  is  a  reasonable  one.  Without  some  knowledge  of 
the  economic  conditions  of  the  industry,  the  state  of  trade, 
the  number  of  orders  in  hand  or  to  be  expected,  and  the 
condition  of  the  labor  market,  his  judgment  of  the  opportune- 
ness or  strategic  advantage  of  the  men's  demand  will  be  of 
no  value.  The  mechanic  kept  working  for  fifty  or  sixty 
hours  a  week  at  one  narrow  process  in  a  single  establishment 
would  be  an  extraordinary  genius  if  he  could  acquire  this 
information.  Nor  would  a  knowledge  of  the  facts  alone 
suffice.  The  best  kit  of  tools  will  not  make  a  man  a  good 
carpenter  without  that  training  in  their  use  which  experience 
alone  can  give.  The  quick  apprehension  and  mental  agility 
which  make  up  the  greater  part  of  the  art  of  using  facts  are 
not  fostered  by  days  spent  in  physical  toil.  Finally,  the 
perfect  negotiator,  like  the  perfect  carpenter,  attains  his 


1 82  Trade  Union  Fimction 

expertness  only  by  incessant  practice  of  his  art.  Here  again, 
the  workman  is  at  a  special  disability  compared  with  the 
captain  of  industry.  The  making  of  bargains  and  agree- 
ments, which  occupies  only  an  infinitesimal  fraction  of  a 
workman's  life  and  thought,  makes  up  the  daily  routine  of 
the  commercial  man. 

These  considerations  have  slowly  overcome  the  work- 
man's objections,  and  have,  in  the  most  powerful  unions, 
together  comprising  over  a  third  of  the  aggregate  member- 
ship, caused  the  bulk  of  the  Collective  Bargaining  to  be 
gradually  transferred  from  the  non-commissioned  officers  to 
the  salaried  civil  service  of  the  movement.  Especially  in 
the  piecework  trades  has  the  amateur  negotiator  most  clearly 
demonstrated  his  inefficiency.  When  the  workman's  re- 
muneration depends  on  a  combination  of  many  different  and 
constantly  changing  factors — the  novelty  of  the  pattern,  the 
character  of  the  material,  the  variations  in  the  machinery, 
the  speed  of  the  engine — success  in  bargaining  demands,  in 
addition  to  all  the  other  qualifications,  a  special  aptitude  for 
quickly  seizing  the  net  result  of  proposed  changes  in  one  or 
more  of  the  factors.  It  is  in  the  piecework  trades  therefore 
that  we  find  the  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining  in  its 
most  highly  developed  form.  The  great  staple  industries  of 
cotton,  coal,  and  iron,  together  with  boot  and  shoe-making, 
and  the  hosiery  and  lace  trades,  have  especially  developed 
elaborate  and  complicated  organisations  for  Collective  Bar- 
gaining which  have  excited  the  admiration  of  economic 
students  all  over  the  world. 

We  must  here  plunge  into  a  maze  of  complicated 
technical  detail  relating  to  these  industries,  each  of  which 
has  developed  its  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining  in  its 
own  way,  and  we  despair  of  making  the  reader  understand 
either  our  exposition  or  our  criticism  unless  he  will  keep 
constantly  in  mind  one  fundamental  distinction,  which  is  all- 
important.  This  vital  distinction  is  between  the  making  of 
a  new  bargain,  and  the  interpreting  of  the  terms  of  an 
existing  one.  Where  the  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          1 83 

has  broken  down,  we  usually  discover  that  this  distinction 
has  not  been  made ;  and  it  is  only  where  this  fundamental 
distinction  has  been  clearly  maintained  that  the  machinery 
works  without  friction  or  ill-feeling.  Let  us  consider  first 
the  interpretation  of  an  existing  bargain.  Directly  a  general 
agreement  or  formal  treaty  has  been  concluded  in  any  trade 
between  the  general  body  of  employers,  on  the  one  hand, 
and  the  general  body  of  workmen  on  the  other,  there  arises 
a  practically  incessant  series  of  disputes  as  to  the  applica- 
tion of  the  agreement  to  particular  cases.  Thus,  as  we  shall 
see,  the  highly  elaborate  and  precisely  detailed  lists  of  the 
English  Cotton-spinners  do  not  prevent,  in  one  or  other  of 
the  thousands  of  mills  to  which  they  apply,  the  almost 
daily  occurrence  of  a  difference  of  opinion  between  employer 
and  operative  as  to  the  wages  due.  Similarly  the  unanimous 
agreement  of  a  "  uniform  statement "  in  the  boot  and  shoe 
trade  leaves  open  endless  questions  as  to  the  classification  of 
the  ever-changing  patterns  called  for  by  the  fashion  of  each 
season.  The  determination  of  the  "  county  average  "  of  the 
Northumberland  or  Durham  coalminer  leaves  it  still  to  be 
determined  what  tonnage  rate  should  be  fixed  for  any 
particular  seam,  in  order  that  the  workmen  may  earn  the 
normal  wage.  The  point  at  issue  in  these  cases  is  not  the 
amount  per  week  which  the  workmen  in  any  particular 
establishment  should  be  permitted  to  earn — for  that  has,  in 
principle,  already  been  settled — but  the  rate  at  which,  under 
the  actual  conditions  of  that  establishment,  and  the  class  of 
goods  in  question,  the  piecework  price  must  be  computed  in 
order  that  the  average  earnings  of  a  particular  section  of 
workmen  shall  amount  to  no  more  and  no  less  than  the 
agreed  standard.  This,  it  will  be  seen,  is  exclusively  an 
issue  of  fact,  in  which  both  the  desires  and  the  tactical 
strength  of  the  parties  directly  concerned  must  be  entirely 
eliminated.  For  conciliation,  compromise,  and  balancing  of 
expediencies,  there  is  absolutely  no  room.  On  the  other 
hand,  it  is  indispensable  that  the  ascertainment  of  facts 
should  attain  an  almost  scientific  precision.  Moreover,  the 


184  Trade  Union  Function 

settlement  should  be  automatic,  rapid,  and  inexpensive. 
The  ideal  machinery  for  this  class  of  cases  would,  in  fact, 
be  a  peripatetic  calculating-machine,  endowed  with  a  high 
degree  of  technical  knowledge,  which  could  accurately 
register  all  the  factors  concerned,  and  unerringly  grind  out 
the  arithmetical  result. 

When  we  come  to  the  settlement  of  the  terms  upon 
which  a  new  general  agreement  should  be  entered  into,  an 
entirely  different  set  of  considerations  is  involved.  Whether 
the  general  level  of  wages  in  the  trade  should  be  raised  or 
lowered  by  I  o  per  cent  ;  whether  the  number  of  boys  to 
be  engaged  by  any  one  employer  should  be  restricted,  and  if 
so,  by  what  scale  ;  whether  the  hours  of  labor  should  be 
reduced,  and  overtime  regulated  or  prohibited, — are  not 
problems  which  could  be  solved  by  even  the  most  perfect 
calculating-machine.  Here  nothing  has  been  decided,  or 
accepted  in  advance  by  both  parties,  and  the  fullest  possible 
play  is  left  for  the  arts  of  diplomacy.  In  so  far  as  the  issue 
is  left  to  Collective  Bargaining  there  is  not  even  any  question 
of  principle  involved.  The  workmen  are  frankly  striving  to 
get  for  themselves  the  best  terms  that  can  permanently  be 
exacted  from  the  employers.  The  employers,  on  the  other 
hand,  are  endeavouring,  in  accordance  with  business  prin- 
ciples, to  buy  their  labor  in  the  cheapest  market.  The  issue  is 
a  trial  of  strength  between  the  parties.  Open  warfare — the 
stoppage  of  the  industry — is  costly  and  even  disastrous  to 
both  sides.  But  though  neither  party  desires  war,  there  is 
always  the  alternative  of  fighting  out  the  issue.  The 
resources  and  tactical  strength  of  each  side  must  accordingly 
exercise  a  potent  influence  on  the  deliberations.  The  pleni- 
potentiaries must  higgle  and  cast  about  to  find  acceptable 
alternatives,  seeking,  like  ambassadors  in  international  con- 
ference, not  to  ascertain  what  are  the  facts,  nor  yet  what 
is  the  just  decision  according  to  some  ethical  standard  or 
view  of  social  expediency,  but  to  find  a  common  basis  which 
each  side  can  bring  itself  to  agree  to,  rather  than  go  to  war. 
Finally,  however  wise  may  be  the  decision  come  to,  the 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          1 85 

acceptance  and  carrying  out  of  the  collective  bargain 
ultimately  arrived  at,  depends  upon  the  extent  to  which  the 
negotiators  express  the  feelings  and  command  the  confidence 
of  the  whole  class  affected.  All  these  considerations  must 
be  taken  carefully  into  account  in  the  formation  of  successful 
machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining. 

The  most  obvious  form  of  permanent  machinery  for 
Collective  Bargaining  is  a  joint  committee,  consisting  of 
equal  numbers  of  representatives  of  the  employers  and  work- 
men respectively.  This  may  almost  be  called  the  "  orthodox  " 
panacea  of  industrial  philanthropists.  For  over  thirty  years, 
since  the  experiments  of  Sir  Rupert  Kettle  and  Mr.  Mun- 
della,  employers  and  workmen  have  been  persistently  urged 
to  adopt  the  form  of  a  "  board  of  arbitration  and  concilia- 
tion," consisting  of  representatives  of  each  side,  and  with  or 
without  an  impartial  chairman  or  an  umpire.  Such  a  joint 
committee,  it  has  been  supposed,  could  thrash  out  in  friendly 
discussion  all  points  in  dispute,  and  arrive  at  an  amicable 
understanding.  In  intractable  cases,  the  umpire's  decision 
would  cut  the  Gordian  knot.  Readers  of  the  History  of 
Trade  Unionism  will  remember  how  eagerly  this  idea  was 
taken  up  by  the  organised  workmen  in  certain  great 
industries,  and  how,  in  coalmining  and  iron  and  steel  in 
particular,  it  has  since  enjoyed  the  favor  both  of  employers 
and  employed.  We  need  not  stop  to  describe  all  the  cases 
in  which  this  form  of  machinery  has,  from  time  to  time,  been 
adopted.  We  shall  best  understand  its  operation  by  con- 
sidering a  couple  of  leading  instances,  the  "  joint  boards  "  of 
the  boot  and  shoe  trade,  and  the  "  joint  committees  "  of  the 
Northumberland  and  Durham  coalminers. 

The  great  machine  industry  of  boot  and  shoe-making 
has  been  provided,  for  some  years  past,  with  a  formal  and 
elaborate  constitution,  mutually  agreed  to  by  employers  and 
employed,  and  expressly  designed  "  to  prevent  a  strike  or 
lock-out,  and  to  secure  the  reference  of  all  trade  disputes  to 
arbitration."  J  The  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining  thus 

1  Rules  for  the  Prevention  of  Strikes  and  Lockouts,  etc.,  i6th  August  1892, 


1 86  Trade  Union  Function 

established  puts  into  concrete  form  all  the  aspirations  of 
enthusiastic  advocates  of  "  industrial  peace."  We  have  first 
a  "  local  board  of  conciliation  and  arbitration "  in  every 
important  centre  of  the  trade.  To  this  board,  formed  of 
an  equal  number  of  elected  representatives  of  the  local 
employers  and  the  local  Trade  Unionists,  must  be  referred 
"every  question,  or  aspect  of  a  question,  affecting  the 
relations  of  employers  and  workmen  individually  or  col- 
lectively." If  the  board  cannot  agree,  the  question  goes 
to  an  impartial  umpire,  acceptable  to  both  sides.  Issues 
affecting  the  whole  industry  were,  until  1894,  dealt  with  by 
a  national  conference  of  great  dignity  and  importance. 
Nine  chosen  leaders  of  the  Federated  Associations  of  Boot 
and  Shoe  Manufacturers  of  Great  Britain  met,  in  the  council 
chamber  of  the  Leicester  Town  Hall,  an  equal  number  of 
elected  representatives  of  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and 
Shoe  Operatives.  These  elaborate  debates,  conducted  with 
all  the  ceremony  of  a  State  Trial,  were  presided  over  by  an 
eminent  and  universally  respected  solicitor,  sometime  mayor 
of  the  town.  If  no  agreement  could  be  arrived  at,  the 
conference  enjoyed  the  services,  as  umpire,  of  no  less  an 
authority  than  Sir  Henry  (now  Lord)  James,  formerly 
Attorney-General,  before  whom,  sitting  as  a  judge,  the  issue 
was  elaborately  reargued  by  the  spokesmen  of  each  side. 
Finally  as  a  means  of  influencing  the  public  opinion  of  the 
trade,  there  were  published,  not  only  the  precise  and 
authoritative  decisions  of  the  conference  or  the  umpire,  but 
also  a  verbatim  report  of  all  the  proceedings.1 

We    can    imagine     how    this     elaborate    and    carefully 
thought  out  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining  would  have 

appended  to  Report  of  Conference,  1892.  These  rules,  which  are  signed  by 
three  employers  and  three  workmen,  on  behalf  of  their  respective  associations, 
consist  of  fifteen  clauses  defining  the  constitution  and  method  of  working  both 
of  the  "Local  Board  of  Conciliation  and  Arbitration,"  and  of  the  "National 
Conference."  They  will  be  found  in  the  Board  of  Trade  Report  on  Strikes  and 
Lockouts  0/1893,  c>  7566  of  1894,  pp.  253-257. 

2  The  "transcript  of  the  shorthand  writers'  notes"  of  the  Conference  of  August 
1892,  and  the  subsequent  trial  before  the  umpire,  forms  a  volume  of  152  pages 
of  rich  material  for  the  student  of  industrial  organisation. 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          1 8  7 

delighted  the  heart  of  the  enthusiastic  believers  in  "  boards 
of  conciliation  and  arbitration."  Nor  need  it  be  contested 
that  it  has  been  the  means  of  effecting  many  peaceful  settle- 
ments in  the  industry.  But  we  do  not  think  that  any  one 
conversant  with  the  trade,  or  any  student  of  the  voluminous 
reports  of  the  proceedings,  will  deny  that  the  boards  have 
been  the  cause  of  endless  friction,  discontent,  and  waste  of 
energy  among  workmen  and  employers  alike.  Scarcely  a 
quarter  passes  without  the  operatives,  in  some  district  or 
another,  revolting  against  their  local  board  ;  condemning  or 
withdrawing  their  representatives ;  and  even  occasionally 
refusing  to  obey  the  award  of  the  umpire.1  The  employers 
are,  on  their  side,  no  better  satisfied  than  the  men,  and  in 
1894  the  national  conference  was  brought  to  an  end  by  the 
secession  of  the  federated  manufacturers,  and  their  resolute 
refusal  to  submit  the  issues  to  arbitration.  The  result  was  a 
stoppage  in  1895  of  practically  the  entire  industry  from  one 
end  of  the  kingdom  to  the  other,  which  was  only  brought  to 
an  end  by  the  half-authoritative  interference  of  the  Board  of 
Trade.2 

If  we  examine  this  general  discontent  we  find  it  taking 
different  forms  among  the  workmen  and  the  employers 
respectively.  The  operatives  complain  that,  when  a  general 
agreement  has  been  concluded  they  cannot  get  any  speedy 
or  certain  enforcement  of  it  through  the  local  boards. 
Thus,  the  Bristol  representative  at  the  annual  delegate 
meeting  in  1894,  complained  bitterly  of  the  dilatory  way  in 
which  his  local  board  acted  in  its  interpretation  work. 
Questions  "  had  been  hanging  about  from  six  to  nine  months 
from  the  board  to  the  umpire.  Decisions  had  been  given 
by  the  umpire  on  boots  after  a  delay  of  eight  or  nine 

1  The  local  boards,  of  which  twelve  were  in  existence  at  the  end  of  1894, 
date  from    1875.     The   Stafford   Board  was  dissolved  in   1878,  and  the  Leeds 
Board  in  1881.     The  years  1891-94  saw  no  fewer  than  seven  dissolutions,  and 
the  important  centres  of  Stafford,  Manchester,  and  Kingswood  still  remain  without 
boards.     The  National  Conference,  established  in  August   1892,  met  five  times 
in  the  next  three  years,  the  sittings  being  suspended  on  the  withdrawal  of  the 
employers  in  December  1894. 

2  See  the  Labour  Gazette,  April  and  May  1895. 


1 88  Trade  Union  Function 

months.  ...  In  one  case  in  the  factory  where  he  worked  a 
boot  was  sent  to  the  arbitration  board,  and  thence  to  the 
umpire.  The  decision  arrived  at  by  the  latter  was  in  favor 
of  the  men.  There  was  something  like  seven  shillings  each 
due  to  two  or  three  men  on  that  particular  boot.  But  one 
of  them  had  left  the  town  in  the  interim,  and  the  result  of 
the  delay  was  that  he  was  practically  swindled  out  of  the 
seven  shillings.  New  samples  had  been  introduced  at  the 
beginning  of  the  year,  and  the  shoes  had  been  made  under 
protest,  at  a  price  the  employers  had  quoted,  till  the  end  of 
the  season.  Then,  perhaps,  when  the  season  was  ended, 
they  got  a  decision  in  their  favor,  face  to  face  with  all  the 
difficulties  of  getting  back  the  money  due  to  them.  .  .  . 
This  continual  delay  sickened  the  whole  of  them  in  Bristol, 
and  although  there  had  not  been  a  ballot  taken  on  the 
question  of  arbitration  in  Bristol,  he  felt  sure  there  were  over 
ninety  per  cent  of  the  men  opposed  to  it."  ] 

The  Kingswood  Local  Board  broke  up  in  1894,  the 
umpire  resigning  his  post  in  disgust.  Discussion  had  pro- 
ceeded upon  a  "  statement "  for  "  light "  boots,  and  points 
in  dispute  were  submitted  to  the  umpire  by  the  board.  The 
bulk  of  the  manufacturers  thereupon  flatly  refused  to  send 
any  samples  of  the  boots  in  question,  and  thus  made  it  im- 
possible for  the  umpire  to  decide  the  cases  submitted  to  him.2 
This  produced  the  greatest  possible  irritation  among  the  men, 
who  urged  that,  as  the  employers  had  failed  to  submit  to  the 
umpire's  award,  the  operatives'  claim  should  be  adopted. 
These  cases  might  be  indefinitely  multiplied  from  all  the 
centres  of  the  industry.  But  delay  is  not  the  only  objection 
brought  by  the  operatives  against  the  working  of  the  local 
boards.  When  at  last  the  umpire's  decision  has  been  given 
it  has  often  failed  to  command  the  assent,  and  sometimes 
even  to  secure  the  obedience  of  the  workmen.  This  arises, 
we  believe,  from  the  class  of  umpire  whom  it  has  been 

1  Report  of  the  Edinburgh  Conference,  May  1894  (the  delegate  meeting  of 
the  National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives). 

2  Shoe  and  Leather  Record,  3<Dth  November  1894. 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          189 

necessary  to  choose.  The  questions  of  interpretation  neces- 
sarily turn,  not  on  any  general  principle,  but  on  extremely 
technical  trade  details,  which  are  unintelligible  to  any  person 
outside  the  industry.1  In  the  absence  of  any  paid  pro- 
fessional expert,  permanently  engaged  for  precisely  this 
work,  the  umpire  has  in  practice  to  be  chosen  from  among 
the  employers,  the  board  usually  agreeing  upon  a  leading 
manufacturer  in  another  district.  This  reliance  on  the 
unpaid  service  of  a  non-resident  increases  the  delay.  But 
what  is  more  important  is,  that  however  generally  respected 
such  an  umpire  may  be,  it  is  inevitable  that,  when  his  award 
runs  counter  to  the  claim  of  the  operatives,  these  should 
accuse  him  of  class  bias.  The  alternative  of  choosing  one 
of  the  officials  of  the  union  would,  it  need  hardly  be  said,  be 
equally  distasteful  to  the  employers. 

The  discontent  of  the  employers  is  directed  chiefly  to 
another  feature  of  the  organisation.  The  work  of  the  local 
boards  is  so  laborious  and  incessant  that  the  great  magnates 
of  the  industry  cannot  spare  time  to  attend.  On  questions 
of  interpretation,  they  would  be  willing  to  leave  the  busi- 
ness to  their  managers  or  smaller  employers.  But  besides 
questions  of  interpretation  the  local  board  have  perpetually 
brought  before  them  disputes  which  turn  upon  the  admission  of 
what  the  employers  regard  as  "  new  principles."  If  the  local 
board,  with  the  concurrence  of  its  employer-members,  decides 
the  issue,  all  the  other  employers  in  the  district,  some  of 
whom  may  be  "  captains  of  industry  "  on  a  huge  scale,  find 
a  new  regulation  made  binding  on  them  in  the  conduct  of 
what  they  regard  as  "  their  own  business."  If  on  the  other 
hand  the  local  board  remits  such  issues — virtually  the 

1  Thus  the  umpire  for  the  Norwich  Local  Board  had  to  award  rates  to  be 
paid  in  the  following  cases,  remitted  from  a  single  meeting,  (i)  "A  woman's 
5ths  if  changed  from  self- vamp  to  calf  vamp;  (2)  a  girl's  4ths  if  changed  from 
self-vamp  to  glace  kid  vamp  ;  (3)  a  woman's  4th's  ditto  ;  (4)  a  girl's  kid  button 
levant  seal  vamp  or  golosh  ;  (5)  a  girl's  glace  kid  one  finger  strap  ;  (6)  a  woman's 
kid  elastic  mock  button  front  shoe  sew-round."  The  award,  which  is  equally 
unintelligible  to  the  general  reader,  will  be  found  in  the  Shoe  and  Leather  Record 
Annual for  1892-93,  p.  121. 


190  Trade  Union  Function 

conclusion  of  new  general  agreements — to  the  national  con- 
ference, all  the  employers  in  the  kingdom  find  themselves 
in  a  similar  predicament.  Moreover,  in  a  publicly  conducted 
national  conference,  formed  of  equal  numbers  from  each 
party,  neither  the  representative  workmen  nor  the  representa- 
tive employers  dare  concede  anything  to  their  opponents,  or 
even  submit  to  a  compromise.  The  result  is  that  every 
important  issue  is  inevitably  remitted  by  the  conference  to 
the  umpire.  Lord  James  has  accordingly  found  himself  in 
the  remarkable  position  of  imposing  laws  upon  the  entire 
boot  and  shoe-making  industry,  prescribing  for  instance,  not 
only  a  minimum  rate  of  wages,  but  also  a  precise  numerical 
limitation  of  the  number  of  boy-learners  to  be  engaged  by 
each  employer,  the  conditions  under  which  alone  a  wholesale 
trader  may  give  work  out  to  sub-contractors,  and  the  extent 
to  which  employers  shall  themselves  provide  workshop 
accommodation,  and  the  date  before  which  such  premises 
shall  be  in  use.  This,  it  is  obvious,  goes  beyond  Collective 
Bargaining.  The  awards  of  Lord  James  amount,  in  fact, 
to  legislative  regulation  of  the  industry,  the  legislature  in 
this  case  being,  not  a  representative  assembly  acting  on 
behalf  of  the  whole  community,  but  a  dictator  elected  by  the 
trade.1 

It  is  therefore  not  surprising  to  find  the  employers 
quickly  protesting  against  so  drastic  and  far-reaching 
an  arrangement.  But  it  was  one  to  which  they  had  ex- 
plicitly and  unreservedly  pledged  themselves.  They  had 
promised,  by  the  rules  of  the  i6th  August  1892,  that 
"  every  question  or  aspect  of  a  question  affecting  the 
relations  of  employers  and  workmen  individually  or  collectively 
should  in  case  of  disagreement  be  submitted  for  settlement," 
first  to  the  local  board,  then  to  the  national  conference,  and 

1  It  is  a  minor  grievance  of  the  employers  that  no  distinguished  lawyer 
can  be  found  to  give  the  unpaid  and  laborious  service  of  an  umpire,  who  is  not 
also  a  politician.  It  is  impossible  for  the  employers  to  avoid  the  suspicion 
that  any  politician  will  be  unconsciously  biassed  in  favor  of  the  most  numerous 
section  of  the  electors.  See  the  significant  quotation  given  in  the  footnote  at 
p.  240. 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          1 9 1 

finally,  if  need  be,  to  the  umpire.  That  this  promise  was 
not  confined  to  questions  of  interpretation  is  made  manifest 
by  the  express  mention  in  the  same  document  of  the  settle- 
ment of  disputes  involving  "  new  principles."  In  the  long 
discussion  which  led  up  to  the  signing  of  the  rules,  they 
had,  in  fact,  successfully  pleaded  for  adopting  "  honestly  and 
unreservedly  arbitration  pure  and  simple,  and  for  every 
dispute,  and  under  all  conditions." *  In  their  anxiety  to 
remove  every  chance  of  a  stoppage  of  their  industry,  they 
had  overlooked  the  fundamental  distinction  between  questions 
of  the  interpretation  of  an  existing  contract  and  questions 
as  to  the  terms  of  a  new  settlement.  If  they  had  listened 
to  the  warning  of  the  able  editor  of  their  own  trade  organ, 
they  would  not  have  made  this  blunder.  The  very  month 
before  the  conference  of  1892  he  was  urging  exactly  the 
distinction  upon  which  we  insist.  "  Employers,"  he  wrote, 
"have  never  contended  that  arbitration  would  settle  every 
conceivable  kind  of  dispute  between  capital  and  labor. 
But  they  have  contended  that  where  certain  established 
principles  are  already  recognised  by  both  szdesy  the  adjustment 
of  details  can  better  be  settled  by  arbitration  than  in  any 
other  way.  ...  It  must  be  obvious  that,  whatever  the 
future  may  bring,  employers  could  not  now  prudently  allow 
every  dispute  with  their  workmen  to  be  settled  by  a  third 
person.  To  say  nothing  of  the  question  of  boy  labor  which 
is  now  at  issue,  a  number  of  others  may  be  mentioned 
regarding  which  the  employer  could  not  consent  to  surrender 
any  portion  of  his  discretion  or  responsibility." 2  The  sub- 
sequent events  quickly  proved  that  this  view  of  the  state 
of  mind  of  the  average  employer  was  correct,  and  that  the 
chosen  representatives  of  the  Federated  Associations  of  Boot 
and  Shoe  Manufacturers  had  failed  to  understand  the  words 
which  they  were,  with  all  solemnity,  using.  When  the 

1  Speech   of  Mr.    Gale,   a   leading   employer.     Third   day  of  Conference, 
August  1892.     The  men  had  wished  to  exclude  any  question  of  a  general  reduc- 
tion of  wages,  whereupon  the  employers  had  insisted  that  no  exception  whatever 
should  be  made. 

2  Shoe  and  Leather  Record^  July  1892. 


192  Trade  Union  Function 

workmen  brought  up  cases  of  actual  disputes  that  had  arisen 
about  boy  labor,  machinery,  the  "team  system,"  and  the 
employment  of  non-unionists,  the  employers  protested  that 
they  had  never  meant  such  questions  as  these  to  be  discussed 
at  all.  The  president  had,  of  course,  no  alternative  but  to 
hold  them  bound  to  their  explicit  agreement,  and  to  overrule 
their  protests.  After  prolonged  ill-feeling,  the  associated 
employers  revolted,  and  withdrew  their  representatives  from 
the  national  conference,  alleging  first  of  all,  that  the  work- 
men had  in  some  cases  refused  to  abide  by  the  award  of 
the  umpire,  and  further,  that  the  national  conference  had 
become  "  a  legislative  tribunal  for  the  trade."  * 

Thus  experience  of  the  working  of  the  elaborate  machinery 
for  Collective  Bargaining  provided  in  the  boot  and  shoe 
industry  has  revealed  many  imperfections.  Some  of  these 
have  been  avoided  in  our  second  example,  the  conciliation 
boards  and  the  joint  committees  of  the  Northumberland  and 
Durham  coalminers.  Here  we  have,  to  begin  with,  a  clear 
distinction  maintained  between  the  machinery  for  interpreta- 
tion and  that  for  concluding  a  new  agreement.  The  earnings 
of  the  miners  in  both  counties  are  determined  ultimately  by 
general  principles2  applicable  to  the  whole  of  each  county, 
which  are  revised  at  occasional  conferences  of  representative 

1  Manifesto  of  Federated  Associations  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Manufacturers  of 
Great  Britain,  2Oth  December  1894.     For  documents  and  exact  particulars  of 
the  dispute  which  thereupon  arose,  see  Labour  Gazette,  April  and  May  1895  > 
also  the  Shoe  and  Leather  Record^  and  the  Monthly  Reports  of  the  National  Union 
of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  from  October  1894  to  June  1895.     We  nave  here 
dealt  with  the  matter,  not  on  its  merits,  but  only  in  so  far  as  it  illustrates  the 
machinery  for  collective  bargaining.     The  agreement  brought  about  by  the  Board 
of  Trade  on  igth  April  1895,  which  now  governs  the  industry,  expressly  excludes 
four  specified  subjects  from  discussion  by  the  local  boards  and  makes  no  provision 
for  a  national  conference.      But  so  far  as  we  understand  the  document,  no  dis- 
tinction is  even  now  made  between  questions  of  interpretation  and  questions  as 
to  the  terms  of  a  new  agreement.      Both  kinds  of  questions  are,  as  before,  to  be 
decided  where  necessary  by  the  umpire. 

2  These   general  principles  include  a  normal  standard  wage,  with  a  corre- 
sponding normal  tonnage  rate,  applicable  to  the  whole  county.     This  is  called 
the  "  County  Average,"  a  somewhat  misleading  phrase  as  the  normal  rate  is  not, 
and  has  long  not  been,  a  precise  "average"  of  the  actual  earnings  of  all  the 
miners  in  the  county,  and  is  now  only  a  conventional  figure  upon  which  percentages 
of  advance  or  reduction  are  based. 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          \  93 

workmen  and  employers.1  Neither  in  Durham  nor  in 
Northumberland  has  this  board  of  conciliation  anything  to 
do  with  the  interpretation  of  the  formal  agreement  from  time 
to  time  arrived  at,  or  with  the  incessant  labor  involved  in 
its  application.  Its  meetings,  held  only  at  rare  intervals, 
command  the  presence  of  the  greatest  coal-owners  in  the 
county,  and  of  the  most  influential  miners'  leaders  specially 
elected  for  the  purpose.  The  board  deliberates  in  private, 
and  publishes  only  its  decisions.  Resort  to  the  umpire, 
or  in  Northumberland  to  the  casting  vote  of  the  chairman, 
is  rare,  the  usual  practice  being  for  a  frank  interchange 
of  views  to  go  on  until  a  basis  of  agreement  can  be 
found.  On  the  other  hand,  all  questions  of  interpretation  or 
application  are  dealt  with  by  another  tribunal,  which  goes 
on  undisturbed  even  when  one  or  other  party  has  temporarily 
withdrawn  its  representatives  from  the  board  of  conciliation. 
In  marked  distinction  from  the  conciliation  board,  the  "joint 
committee  "  in  each  county  meets  frequently,  and  is  engaged 
in  incessant  work.  But  this  committee  is  expressly  debarred 
from  dealing  with  "  such  as  may  be  termed  county  questions, 
or  which  may  affect  the  general  trade,"  2  and  is  rigidly  con- 
fined to  the  application  of  the  existing  general  agreement  to 
particular  mines  or  seams.3 

1  In  Durham  this  conference  is,  since  February  1895,  called  "The  Board  of 
Conciliation  for  the  Coal  Trade."     The  rules  of  that  date  provide  for  eighteen 
representatives  of  each  side,  with  an  umpire  to  be  mutually  agreed  upon,  or  in 
default  nominated  by  the  Board  of  Trade.     In  Northumberland,  the  corresponding 
"  Board  of  Conciliation  "  now  consists  of  fifteen  on  each  side,  with  an  independent 
chairman  having  a  casting  vote,  to  be  nominated,  in  default  of  agreement,  by  the 
Chairman  of  the  Northumberland  County  Council.     The  name  and  constitution 
of  these  boards  are  frequently  varied  in  minor  details. 

2  Durham  Miners'  Joint  Committee  Rules,  November  1879. 

3  Owing  to  the  great  differences  in  the  ease  and  facilities  with  which  the  coal 
is  got  in  different  mines  and  different  seams  of  the  same  mine,  it  is  impossible, 
consistently  with  uniformity  in  the  rate  of  payment  for  the  whole  work  done,  to 
apply  any  identical  tonnage  rate  throughout  the  county.     When  it  is  found  that 
the  men  in  any  mine  constantly  earn  per  day  an  amount  which  departs  appreciably 
from  the  normal  (the  so-called  "  County  Average"),  the  employer  or  the  work- 
men appeal  for  a  readjustment  of  the  tonnage  rate  in  that  particular  instance.      It 
must  be  counted  as   a  grave  defect  in  the  miners'  organisations  outside  North- 
umberland and  Durham  that  no  systematic  arrangements  exist  for  this  adjust- 
ment of  the  standard  wage  to  the  particular  circumstances  of  each  mine  or  seam. 

VOL.  I  O 


194  Trade  Union  Function 

For  deliberateness  and  impartiality  this  tribunal  leaves 
nothing  to  be  desired.  The  members,  all  of  whom  are 
practically  acquainted  with  the  industry,  do  not  directly 
represent  either  of  the  parties  concerned  in  any  dispute,  and 
have  no  other  interest  than  that  of  securing  uniformity  in 
the  application  of  a  common  agreement.  The  chief  dis- 
advantage of  the  tribunal  is  that  which  we  have  already 
seen  complained  of  in  the  local  boards  of  the  boot  and  shoe 
trade.  For  deciding  mere  issues  of  fact,  as  to  the  circum- 
stances of  a  particular  seam  or  pit,  a  joint  committee  is 
necessarily  a  cumbrous,  expensive,  and  dilatory  machine. 
Every  case  involves  the  journeying  to  Newcastle  of  witnesses 
on  both  sides,  and  their  examination  by  all  the  members  of 
the  committee.  This  consumes  so  much  time  that  cases 
frequently  stand  in  the  agenda  for  several  months  before 
being  reached,  a  fact  which  leads  to  great  dissatisfaction  to 
those  concerned.1  Moreover,  it  is  often  impossible  to  come 
to  any  decision  without  personal  inspection  of  the  seam,  and 
difficult  cases  are  therefore  constantly  referred  for  decision 
to  one  employer  and  one  workman,  with  power  to  choose  an 
umpire.  This  results  in  a  more  precise  ascertainment  of 
facts,  but  increases  the  delay  and  expense.  Finally,  there  is 
in  such  cases  no  guarantee  that  the  decisions,  arrived  at  by 
different  sets  of  people,  will  preserve  that  exact  uniformity 
which  it  is  the  special  function  of  the  tribunal  to  enforce. 

Thus,  the  much-advertised  expedient  of  a  single  joint 
committee  of  employers  and  employed  to  deal  with  all 
questions  that  arise  between  them,  has  not  proved  a  wholly 

In  Lancashire,  Derbyshire,  and  other  districts  of  the  Miners'  Federation,  for 
instance,  there  is  no  better  protection  of  the  standard  wage  than  pit-lists,  pre- 
scribing tonnage  rates  for  individual  collieries.  No  machinery  exists  for  ensuring 
uniformity  (of  the  rate  of  pay  for  the  amount  of  work)  between  these  lists,  or  even 
for  revising  their  rates  to  meet  the  changing  circumstances  of  particular  seams. 
If  a  miner  finds  he  is  earning  a  very  low  amount  per  day,  he  applies  to  his  lodge 
meeting  for  permission  to  leave  and  receive  strike  benefit.  More  or  less  informal 
negotiations  may  then  be  opened  with  the  mine  manager,  who  often  fixes  a  new 
rate,  in  consultation  either  with  the  group  of  miners  themselves,  or  with  the  lodge 
officials,  or  in  some  instances  with  salaried  agents  of  the  union. 

1  This  is  especially  the  case  in  Durham,  where  the  number  of  mines  dealt 
with  is  very  large. 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          \  95 

satisfactory  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining.  The  ex- 
pediency of  having  separate  machinery  for  the  essentially 
different  processes  of  interpreting  an  existing  agreement  and 
concluding  a  new  one  is,  we  think,  clearly  demonstrated. 
For  one  of  these  two  processes,  the  application  and  inter- 
pretation of  an  existing  agreement,  a  joint  committee  is  a 
cumbrous  and  awkward  device.  A  better  solution  of  the 
problem  has  been  found  in  the  Lancashire  cotton  trade. 
The  cotton  operatives,  like  the  Northumberland  and  Durham 
coalminers,  have  distinguished,  clearly  and  sharply,  between 
the  formation  of  a  new  general  agreement  and  the  applica- 
tion of  an  existing  agreement  to  particular  cases.  But  they 
have  done  more  than  this.  Unconsciously  and,  as  it  were,  in- 
stinctively, they  have  felt  their  way  to  a  form  of  machinery  for 
Collective  Bargaining  which  uses  the  representative  element 
where  the  representative  element  is  needed,  whilst  on  the 
other  hand  it  employs  the  professional  expert  for  work  at 
which  the  mere  representative  would  be  out  of  place. 

We  will  first  describe  the  machinery  for  the  interpreta- 
tion of  an  existing  agreement.  The  factors  which  enter  into 
the  piecework  rates  of  the  Lancashire  cotton  operatives  are 
so  complicated  that  both  the  employers  and  the  workpeople 
have  long  since  recognised  the  necessity  of  maintaining 
salaried  professional  experts  who  devote  their  whole  time  to 
the  service  respectively  of  the  employers'  association  and  the 
Trade  Union.  The  earnings  of  a  cotton-spinner,  for  instance, 
depend  upon  the  complex  interaction  of  such  factors  as  the 
"  draw "  of  the  mule,  the  number  of  its  spindles,  and  the 
speed  with  which  the  machinery  works.  To  compute  the 
operative's  earnings,  even  with  the  aid  of  the  elaborate 
printed  tables  known  as  the  "  List,"  entails  no  ordinary 
amount  of  arithmetical  facility.  But  it  is  especially  the 
custom  of  allowing  the  operative  compensation  for  defective 
material  or  old-fashioned  machinery  and  the  employer  a 
corresponding  allowance  for  improvements,  which  has  thrown 
the  collective  bargaining,  as  regards  interpretation,  entirely 
into  the  hands  of  professional  experts.  Thus,  if  an  Oldham 


196  Trade  Union  Function 

operative  finds  his  earnings  falling  below  the  current  figure, 
either  because  the  raw  cotton  is  inferior  or  the  machinery 
obsolete,  or  if  an  employer  speeds  up  his  engine  or  introduces 
improvements,  the  experts  on  each  side  visit  the  mill,  and 
confer  together  as  to  the  net  effect  of  the  change.  If  the 
deficiency  in  earnings  is  considered  to  be  due  to  imperfection 
in  the  raw  material,  or  to  the  old-fashioned  character  of  the 
machinery,  the  employer  is  required  to  add  a  specified  per- 
centage to  the  normal  piecework  rate,  so  that  the  work- 
man may  not  suffer.  On  the  other  hand,  if  the  employer 
has  effected  special  improvements,  by  which  the  product  is 
augmented,  without  increasing  the  strain  on  the  operative, 
he  is  allowed  to  deduct  a  corresponding  percentage  from  the 
"  List  "  price.  •  The  cotton -weavers  have  what  is  essentially 
the  same  machinery  for  calculating  the  characteristic  technical 
details  of  their  trade. 

The  importance  and  complication  of  the  duties  thus 
entrusted  to  the  salaried  officials  of  the  cotton-spinners'  and 
cotton-weavers'  unions  has  led  to  the  adoption  of  an  interest- 
ing method  of  recruiting  this  branch  of  the  Trade  Union 
Civil  Service.  The  Cotton -weavers,  in  1 86 1,  subjected  the 
candidates  for  the  then  vacant  office  of  general  secretary  to 
a  competitive  examination.1  This  practice  was  adopted  by 
the  Cotton-spinners,  and  is  now  the  regular  way  of  selecting 
all  the  officials  who  are  to  concern  themselves  with  the 
intricate  trade  calculations.  The  branches  retain  the  right  of 

1  Mr.  Thomas  Birtwistle,  the  successful  candidate  on  this  occasion,  was, 
after  over  thirty  years'  honorable  service  of  his  Trade  Union,  appointed  by  the 
Home  Secretary  an  Inspector  in  the  Factory  Department,  as  the  only  person 
competent  to  understand  and  interpret  the  complicated  methods  of  remuneration 
in  the  weaving  trade.  His  son,  brought  up  in  the  Trade  Union  office,  has  since 
also  been  appointed  a  factory  inspector.  The  successful  candidate  at  the  Bolton 
Cotton-spinners'  examination  in  1895  was>  a^er  two  years'  service  as  Trade 
Union  Secretary,  engaged  in  a  similar  capacity  by  the  local  Master  Cotton- 
spinners'  Association.  So  far  as  we  know,  this  is  the  first  instance  of  a  Trade 
Union  official  transferring  his  services  from  the  operatives  to  the  employers,  and  it 
throws  an  interesting  light  on  the  transformation  of  the  "  labor  leader  "  into  the 
professional  accountant.  The  bulk  of  the  daily  work  of  the  Trade  Union 
officials  in  the  cotton  industry  consists,  in  fact,  in  securing  the  uniform  observance 
of  a  collective  agreement,  a  service  which,  like  that  of  a  legal  or  medical  pro- 
fessional  man,  could,  with  equal  propriety,  be  rendered  to  either  client. 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          1 97 

nominating  the  candidates,  and  the  members,  acting  through 
their  Representative  Assembly,  their  right  of  election.  But 
between  the  day  of  nomination  and  that  of  election  all 
the  candidates  submit  to  a  competitive  examination,  con- 
ducted by  the  most  experienced  officers  of  the  unions.  A 
fairly  stiff  paper  is  set  in  the  arithmetic  and  technical  cal- 
culations required  in  the  trade,  and  each  candidate  writes 
an  essay.  But  a  prominent  part  is  played  by  an  oral 
examination,  in  which  the  examiners  assume  the  part  of 
employers,  cross-question  the  candidates  one  by  one  on  the 
alleged  grievances  of  which  they  are  supposed  to  have  come 
to  complain,  and  do  not  refrain,  in  order  to  test  their  wits 
and  their  good  temper,  from  adopting  the  bullying  manners 
of  the  worst  employers.  The  marks  gained  by  all  the  candi- 
dates are  printed  in  full  detail,  the  name  of  the  glib-tongued 
"  popular  leader  "  being  sometimes  followed  by  the  comment 
of  "  entirely  wrong  "  or  "  not  worked  "  in  all  his  arithmetical 
calculations,  and  by  infinitesimal  marks  for  spelling,  writing, 
and  conduct  under  cross-examination.  The  result  is  usually 
the  election  of  the  candidate  who  has  obtained  the  highest 
marks,  but  the  Representative  Assembly  occasionally  exercises 
its  discretion  in  giving  a  preference  to  a  candidate  of  known 
character  or  good  service,  who  has  fallen  a  few  marks  behind 
the  best  examinee.1 

1  OPERATIVE  COTTON-SPINNERS'  PROVINCIAL  ASSOCIATION  OF 
BOLTON  AND  DISTRICT. 

Offices  :  77  St.  George's  Road,  Bolton. 

Examination  Paper  for  Candidates  applying  for  situation  of  Gen.  Sec.  of  the 
above  Association. 

2$th  January  1895. 

Subject  I. — Calculations. 

1.  Find  the  number  of  stretches  put  up  in  a  week,  and  the  price  per   100 
required  to  produce  a  gross  wage  of  £3  :  9  : 7  per  pair  of  mules,  from  the  follow- 
ing particulars  : — Number  of  spindles  in  one  mule,    1090.      From   56^  hours, 
deduct  2j  hours  for  cleaning  and  accidental  stoppages,  and  one  hour  and  ten 
minutes  for  doffing.     Speed  of  each  mule,  4  stretches  in  75  seconds. 

2.  Taking  the  stretches  as  ascertained  by  the  previous  question  to  be  each 


198  Trade  Union  Function 

It  is  to  this  method  of  selection  that  we  attribute  the 
remarkable  success  of  the  officials  of  the  Cotton  Trade  Unions 
in  obtaining  the  best  possible  terms  for  their  members.  We 
regard  it  as  a  great  disadvantage  to  the  Trade  Union  world 
that  the  system  has  not  hitherto  spread  to  other  unions. 
It  seems  to  us  to  combine  the  advantages  of  competitive 
examination  and  popular  selection,  and  it  ensures  the  union 
against  the  serious  calamity  of  finding  itself  saddled  with  an 
incompetent  officer. 

This  part  of  the  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining 
among  the  Cotton  Operatives — the  meeting  of  the  salaried 
professional  experts  on  each  side — deals,  as  we  have  said, 
only  with  questions  of  interpretation,  that  is,  the  application 

64^  inches  long,  how  many  hanks  would  the  week's  production  amount  to,  and 
what  price  per  1000  hanks  would  be  required  to  bring  out  the  wage  previously 
given  ? 

3.  Assuming  the  standard  price  paid  for  producing  a  certain  count  of  yarn  to 
be  I2s.  yd.  per  100  Ibs.,  what  would  the  price  be  after  a  reduction  of  7.9  per 
cent,  and  what  percentage  would  it  require  to  bring  back  the  reduced  price  to 
the  original  amount  ? 

4.  Divide  .3364502  by  .001645. 

5.  Extract  the  square  root  of  8o's  counts  to  three  places  of  decimals,   and 
then  ascertain  the  required  turns  per  inch  for  both  twist  and  weft,  the  assumed 
standard  being  the  square  root  of  the  counts,  multiplied  by  3^  ior  weft,  and  3$ 
for  twist. 

6.  If  good  fair  Egyptian  cotton  is  advanced  from  47Arths  to  4$d.  per  lb.,  what 
would  be  the  rate  per  cent  of  the  increase  ?     Also  what  would  be  the  amount  of 
the  broker's  commission  on  a  sale  of  1000  bales  of  480  Ibs.  each,  at  one-quarter 
of  one  per  cent,  and  what  would  be  the  difference  in  his  commission  as  between 
selling  at  one  price  and  the  other  ? 

7.  An  upright  shaft  runs  at  the  rate  of  80  revolutions  per  minute,  and  has  on 
it  a  wheel  with  70  teeth  driving  a  wheel  with  40  teeth  on  the  line  shaft.      Over 
each  pair  of  mules  there  is  on  the  line  shaft  a  drum  40  inches  in  diameter  driving 
a  counter  pulley  16  inches  in  diameter.     On  the  counter  shaft  is  a  drum  30  inches 
in  diameter,  driving  a  rim-pulley  15  inches  in  diameter.      Give  the  revolutions  of 
the  rim  shaft  per  minute. 

8.  Assuming  a  rim  shaft  to  be  making  680  revolutions  per  minute,  with  a 
2o-inch  rim,  a  ii^-inch  tin  roller-pulley,  a  6-inch  tin  roller,  and  spindle  wharves 
rfths  of  an  inch  in  diameter,   what  will  be  the  number  of  revolutions  of  the 
spindles  per  minute,  after  allowing  T\th  of  an  inch  each  to  the  diameter  of  the  tin 
roller  and  spindle  wharves  for  slipping  of  bands  ? 

17. —  Writing;  Composition,  and  Spelling. 

Compile  an  essay  on  Trade  Unions,   with  special  reference  to  their  useful 
features.     The  essays  must  not  exceed  about   1200  words,  and  the  points  taken 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          \  99 

to  particular  jobs,  or  particular  processes,  of  the  existing 
general  agreements  accepted  by  both  'sides.  When  it  comes 
to  concluding  or  revising  the  general  agreement  itself — a 
matter  in  which  not  one  firm  or  operative  alone  is  interested, 
but  the  whole  body  of  employers  and  workmen — we  find  the 
machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining  taking  the  form  of  a  joint 
committee  composed  of  a  certain  number  of  representatives 
of  each  side.  Thus  the  Cotton-spinners,  whilst  leaving  to 
the  arbitrament  of  the  secretaries  of  the  district  union 
and  district  employers'  association  all  questions  relating  to 
particular  mills  or  particular  workmen,  revise  the  details  of 
their  lists  in  periodical  conferences  in  which  the  leading 
employers  of  the  district  concerned  arrange  the  matter  with 
the  leading  trade  union  officials  and  representative  operatives. 
And  when  the  point  at  issue  is  not  the  alteration  of  the 
technical  details  of  the  list,  but  a  general  reduction  or  advance 
of  wages  by  so  much  per  cent  throughout  the  trade,  or  a 
general  shortening  of  the  working  time,  we  see  the  matter 

into  consideration  will  be  handwriting,  spelling,  composition,  and  the  clear  concise 
marshalling  of  whatever  facts  or  arguments  are  adduced. 

III. — Oral  Examination. 

Each  candidate  will  be  examined  separately  as  to  his  capacity  for  dealing 
orally  with  labour  disputes.  On  this  point  they  will  have  to  formulate  what 
they  consider  would  be  a  complaint  requiring  immediate  attention,  and  the 
examiners  will  question  them,  and  possibly  urge  some  arguments  against  the 
views  advanced. 

Candidates  will  be  allowed  from  ten  in  the  forenoon  to  five  in  the  afternoon 
to  complete  their  examination  in  the  two  first  subjects,  with  one  hour  for  dinner. 
Candidates  will  not  be  allowed  to  refer  to  any  books  or  papers.  The  third 
subject  (oral  examination)  will  not  be  taken  until  Sunday,  the  27th  instant,  at 
I  o'clock. 

THOMAS  ASHTON,  j  Examiners, 
JAS.  MAWDSLEY,    ) 

Thirteen  candidates  in  all  entered  for  this  examination.  The  examiners 
allowed  a  maximum  of  50  marks  for  each  sum,  and  loo  marks  each  for  writing, 
spelling,  composition,  and  oral  examination,  making  800  marks  the  maximum 
attainable.  The  number  of  marks  obtained  by  the  candidates  varied  from  195 
to  630.  The  post  was  finally  given  to  the  second  candidate  in  the  list  (610 
marks),  who  was  an  old  and  esteemed  officer  of  the  union,  and  whose  second 
place  at  the  examination  was  chiefly  due  to  his  obtaining  lower  marks  for  hand- 
writing than  the  most  successful  candidate. 


20O  Trade  Union  Function 

discussed  between  appointed  representatives  of  the  whole 
body  of  the  employers,  attended  by  their  agents  and  solicitors, 
and  the  central  executive  of  the  Amalgamated  Association 
of  Operative  Cotton-spinners  as  representing  all  the  district 
unions. 

In  the  case  of  the  English  Cotton-spinners  the  lists  of 
prices  have  been  so  carefully  and  elaborately  worked  out 
that  even  district  conferences  are  of  only  occasional  occur- 
rence. The  general  policy  of  both  employers  and  operatives 
is  against  any  but  rare  and  moderate  variations  of  the 
standard  earnings.  Such  questions  as  hours  of  labor  and 
sanitation  do  not,  among  the  Cotton  Operatives,  for  reasons 
that  we  shall  explain  in  a  subsequent  chapter,  fall  within  the 
sphere  of  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining.  The  joint 
conferences  of  the  whole  trade  take  place  therefore  only  in 
momentous  crises,  and  are  accompanied  by  all  the  solemnity 
and  strenuousness  of  an  assembly  on  whose  decision  turns 
the  question  of  peace  or  war. 

It  is  interesting  to  see  one  of  these  momentous  confer- 
ences at  work.  The  historic  all-night  sitting  which  settled 
the  great  Cotton-spinners'  dispute  of  1893,  and  concluded 
the  agreement  which  has  since  governed  the  trade,  was 
vividly  described  by  one  of  the  leading  Trade  Union  officials 
who  took  part  in  it.  The  employers  had  demanded  a 
reduction  of  10  per  cent,  whilst  the  men  had  urged  that  it 
would  be  better  to  reduce  the  number  of  hours  worked  per 
week.  The  stoppage  had  lasted  no  less  than  twenty  weeks, 
practically  every  mill  in  the  whole  industry  being  closed. 
Feeling  on  both  sides  had  run  high,  but  after  frequent 
negotiations  and  incessant  newspaper  comment,  the  points 
at  issue  had  been  narrowed  down,  and  both  parties  felt  the 
need  of  bringing  the  struggle  to  an  end.  To  escape  the 
crowd  of  reporters  the  place  of  meeting  was  kept  secret,  and 
fixed  for  3  P.M.  at  a  country  inn,  to  which  the  whole  party 
journeyed  together  in  the  same  train. 

"  On  the  employers'  side  was  Mr.  A.  E.  Rayner,  looking 
all  the  better  for  his  holiday  at  Bournemouth.  With  him 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          201 

were  some  sixteen  or  seventeen  others,  amongst  whom  were 
Mr.  Andrew,  Mr.  John  B.  Tattersall,  and  Mr.  James  Fletcher 
of  Oldham.  There  was  also  Mr.  John  Fletcher,  Mr.  R  S. 
Buckley,  and  Mr.  Smethurst  of  the  Ashton  district,  who 
took  with  them  Mr.  Dixon  to  keep  them  in  countenance. 
Mr.  Sidebottom  of  Stockport  also  gave  a  kind  of  military 
flavor  to  his  colleagues,  whilst  Mr.  John  Mayall  of  Moseley 
attended  to  look  in  and  lend  some  dignity  to  the  occasion, 
in  which  he  was  assisted  by  Mr.  W.  Tattersall,  secretary  of 
the  federation.  On  the  operatives'  side  Mr.  Ashton,  Mr. 
Mellor,  and  Mr.  Jones  did  duty  for  Oldham  ;  Mr.  Wood,  Mr. 
Rhodes,  and  Mr.  Carr  represented  the  Ashton  district ;  whilst 
the  general  business  was  attended  to  by  Mr.  Mullin,  Mr. 
Mawdsley,  Mr.  Fielding,  and  some  dozen  others,  whilst  Mr. 
D.  Holmes,  Mr.  Wilkinson,  and  Mr.  Buckley  had  a  watch- 
ing brief  for  the  winders  and  reelers.  Perhaps  we  ought  not 
to  omit  mentioning  that  the  employers  had  brought  with 
them  Mr.  Hesketh  Booth,  clerk  to  the  Oldham  magistrates, 
who  was  counterbalanced  by  Mr.  Ascroft,  another  Oldham 
solicitor,  who  had  accompanied  the  cardroom  hands. 

"  Those  whose  names  we  have  mentioned,  with  others, 
made  up  a  party  of  between  thirty  and  forty,  and  after  taking 
a  few  minutes  to  straighten  themselves  up  after  leaving  the 
train,  they  settled  down  to  business.  Mr.  A.  E.  Rayner  was 
unanimously  voted  to  the  chair.  .  .  .  Both  sides  had  prepared 
and  got  printed  a  series  of  proposals,  and  the  employers  had 
.  .  .  them  printed  side  by  side  on  the  same  sheet.  In  many 
of  them  there  was  nothing  to  differ  about  except  the  word- 
ing, as  the  idea  aimed  at  was  the  same  in  both  cases.  But 
the  clause  dealing  with  the  reduction  was  the  first,  and  in 
their  sheets  the  employers  had  left  the  amount  out,  whilst 
the  operatives  had  put  in  2\  per  cent.  The  employers  wished 
the  discussion  on  this  point  to  be  deferred  to  the  end  of  the 
meeting,  but  feeling  that  unless  a  settlement  could  be  arrived 
at  on  this,  the  whole  of  the  time  spent  on  the  other  clauses 
would  be  wasted,  the  operatives  insisted  it  should  be  taken 
first.  The  employers  then  retired,  and  after  being  absent  some 


2O2  Trade  Union  Function 

time,  returned  and  offered  to  accept  a  reduction  of  3  per 
cent.  The  operatives  then  retired,  and  after  a  prolonged 
absence,  offered  to  recommend  the  acceptance  of  sevenpence 
in  the  pound.1  Then  came  an  adjournment  for  tea,  and 
further  discussion  on  the  same  subject  followed,  which  was, 
however,  carried  on  by  means  of  deputations  from  one  section 
to  the  other,  as  it  was  found  that  much  better  progress  was 
made  by  this  system  than  by  all  being  together,  with  its 
concomitant  long  speeches,  which  generally  came  to  nothing. 
This  point  ultimately  disposed  of  in  favour  of  the  sevenpence, 
some  minor  clauses  were  got  through,  the  next  discussion 
being  on  the  arrangement  of  intervals  between  the  times 
when  wages  can  be  disturbed.  This  discussion  brought  up 
the  time  to  after  ten  o'clock,  and  everybody  was  tired  and 
anxious  to  be  going  home.  .  .  .  But  as  there  seemed  to  be 
every  prospect  of  being  able  to  ultimately  agree,  it  was  con- 
sidered that  they  should  not  run  the  risk  of  rendering  the 
meeting  useless  by  separating.  In  order  to  give  the  jaded 
men  an  opportunity  for  freshening  up,  an  adjournment  for 
half  an  hour  was  therefore  agreed  to,  during  which  cold 
remains  of  the  tea  vanished.  This,  combined  with  a  smoke 
and  a  stroll  in  the  open  air,  put  everybody  right,  and  when 
business  was  resumed  it  went  on  swimmingly.  There  was 
little  said  by  the  employers  over  their  clause,  that  union 
operatives  must  work  amicably  with  non-union  men,  and 
another  affirming  that  in  any  proposal  to  change  the  rate  of 
wages  the  state  of  trade  for  the  three  previous  years  must  be 
taken  into  account.  .  .  .  When  this  work  was  done  the 
remaining  clauses  which  affirm  the  desirability  of  (employers 
and  operatives)  working  together  for  the  promotion  of 
measures  conducive  to  the  general  interests  of  the  trade,  were 
soon  gone  through,  and  at  nearly  four  o'clock  in  the  morning 
the  jaded  disputants  rushed  off  to  get  a  little  change  of  air 
whilst  the  agreement  was  being  picked  out  from  piles  of 
papers  and  put  together  in  proper  form.  At  this  stage  a 
little  diversion  was  occasioned  by  the  arrival  of  a  cab  con- 

1  Equal  to  2.916  per  cent. 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          203 

taining  a  reporter  of  one  of  the  Manchester  papers,  who, 
after  hunting  all  over  South-east  Lancashire  for  the  meeting- 
place,  had  at  last  found  the  right  spot.  This  bit  of  enterprise 
having  been  rewarded  by  about  six  lines  of  something,  he 
rushed  off  back  to  catch  his  paper.  Just  after  five  (after 
fourteen  hours)  the  documents  were  in  shape,  and  the 
requisite  signatures  attached,  and  with  a  few,  evidently  heart- 
felt congratulatory  remarks  from  the  chairman,  and  a  vote  of 
thanks  having  been  given  to  him,  the  proceedings  closed."  * 

The  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining  developed  by 
the  Cotton  Operatives,  in  our  opinion,  approaches  the  ideal. 
We  have,  to  begin  with,  certain  broad  principles  unreservedly 
agreed  to  throughout  the  trade.  The  scale  of  remuneration, 
based  on  these  principles,  is  worked  out  in  elaborate  detail 
into  printed  lists,  which  (though  not  yet  identical  for  the 
whole  trade)  automatically  govern  the  actual  earnings  of 
the  several  districts.  The  application,  both  of  the  general 
principles  and  of  the  lists,  to  particular  mills  and  particular 
workmen,  is  made,  not  by  the  parties  concerned,  but  by  the 
joint  decision  of  two  disinterested  professional  experts,  whose 
whole  business  in  life  is  to  secure,  not  the  advantage  of 
particular  employer  or  workmen  by  whom  they  are  called  in, 
but  uniformity  in  the  application  of  the  common  agreement 
to  all  employers  and  workmen.  The  common  agreements 
themselves  are  revised  at  rare  intervals  by  representative 
joint  committees,  in  which  the  professional  experts  on  both 
sides  exercise  a  great  and  even  a  preponderating  influence. 
The  whole  machinery  appears  admirably  contrived  to  bring 
about  the  maximum  deliberation,  security,  stability,  and 
promptitude  of  application.  And  whilst  absolutely  no  room 
is  left  for  the  influence  upon  the  negotiations  of  individual 
idiosyncrasies,  temper,  ignorance  of  fact,  or  deficiency  in 
bargaining  power,  whether  on  the  side  of  the  employer  or 

1  "How  matters  were  arranged,"  Cotton  Factory  Times,  3ist  March  1893; 
see  Labour  Gazette,  May  1893.  The  formal  treaty,  known  as  the  "  Brook  lands 
Agreement,"  will  be  found  in  the  Board  of  Trade  Report  on  Wages  and  Hours 
of  Labour,  Part  II.,  Standard  Piece  Rates,  1894,  C,  7567,  p.  10. 


204  Trade  Union  Function 

the  operative,  the  uniform  application  of  an  identical  method 
of  remuneration  throughout  the  whole  trade  leaves  the  able 
capitalist  or  energetic  workman  free  to  obtain  for  himself  the 
full  advantage  of  his  superiority.1 

The  reader  who  has  had  the  patience  to  follow  the  fore- 
going exposition  will  have  seen  that,  taking  the  Trade  Union 
world  as  a  whole,  the  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining 
must  be  regarded  as  extremely  imperfect.  We  do  not  here 
discuss  whether  Collective  Bargaining  is,  or  is  not,  economi- 
cally advantageous  to  the  workmen  or  to  the  community. 
We  may,  however,  assume  that  it  is  desirable,  if  it  exists, 
that  it  should  be  carried  on  without  friction.  And  if  for  the 
moment  we  take  the  Trade  Union  point  of  view,  and  assume 
the  expediency  of  a  Common  Rule,  excluding  the  influence 
of  particular  exigencies,  it  is  essential  that  this  Common 
Rule  should  be  wisely  and  deliberately  determined  on, 
uniformly  applied,  and  systematically  enforced.  This  de- 
mands machinery  which,  over  the  greater  part  of  the  Trade 
Union  world,  has  not  yet  been  developed.  Throughout  the 
great  engineering  and  building  trades,  and  indeed,  in  nearly  all 
the  timework  trades,  Collective  Bargaining,  though  practically 
universal,  is  carried  on  in  a  haphazard  way  with  the  most 
rudimentary  machinery,  and  usually  by  amateurs  in  the  craft 
of  negotiation.  The  piecework  trades  have,  in  the  main, 
been  forced  to  recognise  the  importance  of  commanding  the 
services  of  salaried  professionals  to  deal  with  their  complicated 
lists  of  prices.  Only  among  the  Cotton-spinners  and  Cotton- 
weavers,  however,  do  we  yet  find  any  arrangement  for 
ensuring,  by  a  technical  examination,  for  continuity  of  expert 

1  The  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  whose  hierarchy  of  agreements  we 
have  described,  has,  in  effect,  similar  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining.  New 
agreements  are  concluded  at  meetings  with  the  employers,  in  which  the  expert 
salaried  officials  are  associated,  at  any  rate  in  form,  with  representative  workmen. 
The  machinery  for  interpretation  consists,  in  effect,  of  a  joint  visit  by  salaried 
officials  representing  respectively  the  associated  employers  and  the  Trade  Union. 
"They  had  tried  a  joint  committee  on  the  Tyne,"  said  Mr.  Robert  Knight,  "  but 
the  employers  could  not  spare  the  time,  for  all  their  local  disputes  mostly  required 
visiting,  and  so  they  came  to  prefer  a  reference  to  a  delegate  who  was  their 
representative,  and  he  met  the  men's  delegate  with  the  best  results." — Newcastle 
Leader  "Extra"  on  Conciliation  in  Trade  Disfrites  (Newcastle,  1894),  p.  15. 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          205 

services.  Finally,  we  see  the  whole  machinery  for  Collective 
Bargaining  seriously  hampered,  except  in  two  or  three  trades, 
by  the  failure  to  make  the  vital  distinction  between  inter- 
preting an  existing  wage  contract,  and  negotiating  the  terms 
upon  which  a  new  general  agreement  should  be  entered  into. 
We  must,  in  fact,  conclude  that,  among  the  great  unions 
only  the  Cotton-spinners,  Cotton-weavers,  and  the  Boiler- 
makers, and,  to  a  lesser  extent,  the  North  of  England  and 
Midland  Iron-workers  *  and  the  Northumberland  and  Durham 

1  For  the  rules,  history,  and  working  of  these  Boards,  see  Industrial 'Conciliation , 
by  Henry  Crompton  ;  Industrial  Peace,  by  L.  L.  F.  R.  Price  (London,  1887)  ; 
Sir  Bernhard  Samuelson's  paper  in  February  1876  before  the  British  Iron  Trade 
Association;  the  evidence  before  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor,  1892, 
particularly  that  of  Messrs.  Whitwell  and  Trow,  Group  A,  14,974  to  15,482; 
and  the  summary  of  the  rules  at  p.  368  of  the  Parliamentary  Paper,  c.  6795,  xn- 
Reports  of  their  proceedings  are  given  in  the  monthly  Ironworkers'  Journal,  the 
organ  of  the  Iron  and  Steel  Workers  of  Great  Britain.  Though  these  Boards 
have  repeatedly  been  described,  their  observers  have,  in  our  opinion,  dealt  rather 
with  the  formal  than  with  the  real  constitution,  and  with  the  aspirations  rather 
than  with  the  actual  results  of  the  organisation.  An  important  but  scarcely 
noticed  element  in  the  problem  is  the  fact  that  a  certain  proportion  of  the  work- 
men are  themselves  employers  of  subordinate  labor.  Exactly  what  classes  of 
workmen — puddlers,  millmen,  mechanics,  enginemen,  laborers,  etc. — are  entitled 
to  vote  in  the  election  of  representatives,  and  how  effectively  all  the  different 
grades  are  actually  represented  on  the  Boards,  has  never  been  described.  It  is 
reported  that  a  large  number  of  the  cases  dealt  with  by  the  Midland  Board  at 
any  rate,  concern  differences,  not  between  a  firm  and  its  wage-earners,  but 
between  a  manual-working  sub-contractor  and  his  subordinates,  the  latter  not 
being  represented  on  the  Board.  With  regard  to  the  actual  results  of  the  Boards, 
the  student  would  have  to  investigate  whether  the  rates  fixed  from  time  to  time 
did  not  operate  rather  as  maxima  than  as  minima ;  whether,  that  is  to  say,  the 
incompleteness  and  lack  of  authority  of  both  the  employers'  and  the  workmen's 
organisations  did  not  lead  to  many  firms  taking  advantage  of  the  awards  of  the 
Board  to  stave  off  larger  demands  from  their  workmen,  whilst  at  other  times 
using  their  own  strategic  position  to  compel  the  men  to  accept  lower  terms  than 
the  Board  was  awarding.  In  January  1893,  for  instance,  one  of  the  union 
officials  deplored,  in  a  meeting  of  the  members,  "  the  private  reductions  which 
they  had  submitted  to  all  round,"  in  contravention  of  the  rates  fixed  by  the 
Midland  Board  (Ironworkers1  Journal,  January  1894).  Some  years  later  the 
men's  dissatisfaction  led  to  the  following  manifesto:  "Amongst  large  numbers 
of  the  workmen  there  is  a  growing  opinion  that  the  Board  is  unsatisfactory,  and 
that  it  would  be  to  the  workers'  interests  to  dissolve  it.  It  is  stated  that 
employers  only  appeal  to  the  Wages  Board  when  it  suits  them,  and  that  they 
ignore  its  principles  and  rules,  when  by  so  doing  they  can  take  undue  advantage 
of  their  workmen,  so  that  the  maintenance  of  the  Wages  Board  is  only  beneficial 
to  the  employer  and  prejudicial  to  the  interests  of  the  workmen.  .  .  .  Even  the 
employer  section  fear  to  enforce  adherence  to  its  rules  because  of  giving  offence 
to  those  employers  who  simply  look  upon  the  Board  as  a  convenience  for  imposing 


206  Trade  Union  Function 

Miners,  can  be  said  to  be  adequately  equipped  with  efficient 
machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining. 

The  foregoing  analysis  of  the  Method  of  Collective 
Bargaining,  and  of  the  machinery  by  which  it  is  carried  out, 
will  have  revealed  to  the  student  two  of  its  incidental  charac- 
teristics, which  to  some  persons  appear  as  fatal  evils,  and  to 
others  merely  as  the  "  defects  of  its  qualities."  The  keen 
Individualist  will  scent  an  element  of  compulsion  in  the 
so-called  "  voluntary  "  agreements  governing  the  conditions 
of  a  whole  trade.  The  ardent  advocate  of  "  industrial  peace" 
will  fail  to  discover  any  guarantee  that  the  elaborate  nego- 
tiations between  highly-organised  classes  will  not  end  in  a 
declaration  of  war  instead  of  a  treaty  of  agreement. 

That  some  measure  of  compulsion  is  entailed  by  the 
Method  of  Collective  Bargaining  no  Trade  Unionist  would 
deny.  Trade  Unionists,  as  we  have  explained,  value  Collec- 
tive Bargaining  precisely  because  it  rules  out  of  account  the 
particular  exigencies  of  individual  workmen  or  establishments. 
With  this  exclusion  of  exigencies  there  comes  necessarily 
a  certain  restriction  on  personal  idiosyncrasy,  which  some 
would  describe  as  a  loss  of  liberty.  When,  for  instance,  the 
employers  and  workmen  in  a  Lancashire  town  collectively 
settle  which  week  shall  be  devoted  to  the  annual  "  wake," 
even  the  exceptionally  industrious  cotton-spinner  or  weaver 
finds  himself  bound  to  keep  holiday,  whether  he  likes  it  or 
not.  It  is  impossible  to  make  common  arrangements  for 
numbers  of  men  without  running  counter  to  the  desires  of 
some  of  them.  The  wider  the  range  of  the  Common  Rule, 
and  the  more  perfect  is  the  machinery  for  its  application  and 
enforcement,  the  larger  may  be  the  minority  which  finds 
itself  driven  to  accept  conditions  which  it  has  not  desired. 
It  follows  that  the  Trade  Union  must  provide,  in  its  consti- 

unjust  conditions  upon  their  workmen."  (Official  Circular  from  the  Executive 
Council  of  the  Associated  Iron  and  Steel  Workers  of  Great  Britain,  loth  August 
1896,  in  Ironworkers'  Journal,  September  1896).  For  analogous  cases  under 
the  North  of  England  Hoard,  the  student  should  investigate  the  action  of  the 
Stockton  Malleable  Iron  Company  (see  Ironworkers  Journal,  January  1894). 
and  that  of  the  Barrow  Steel  Works  (Ibid.  January  1896). 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          207 

tution,  some  means  of  securing  the  obedience  of  all  its 
members  to  the  regulations  decided  upon  by  the  majority. 
The  rules  of  all  unions,  from  the  earliest  times  down  to  the 
present  day,  contain  clauses  empowering  the  fining  of  dis- 
obedient members,  the  alternative  to  paying  the  fine  being 
expulsion  from  the  union.  We  have  already  pointed  out 
that  the  development  of  the  friendly  society  side  of  Trade 
Unionism  incidentally  makes  this  sanction  a  penalty  of  very 
real  weight,  and  one  which  can  be  easily  enforced.  To  this 
pecuniary  loss  may,  moreover,  be  added  the  incidents  of 
outlawry.  When  a  union  includes  the  bulk  of  the  workmen 
in  any  industry,  its  members  invariably  refuse  to  work  along- 
side a  man  who  has  been  expelled  from  the  union  for 
"  working  contrary  to  the  interests  of  the  trade."  In  such  a 
case  expulsion  from  the  union  may  easily  mean  expulsion 
from  the  trade.  But  whilst  the  Trade  Union  has  thus  most 
drastic  punishments  at  its  command,  the  individual  member 
is  habitually  protected  from  tyranny  or  caprice  by  an  elab- 
orate system  of  appeals,  which  ensure  him  against  condemna- 
tion otherwise  than  according  to  the  positive  laws  of  his 
community.  This  disciplinary  system  is,  of  course,  usually 
applied  to  men  who  deliberately  undermine  the  Common 
Rule  by  accepting  lower  terms  than  those  collectively  agreed 
to.1  But  it  is  also  used  against  workmen  who  break  the 
agreement  in  the  other  direction.  "  To  give  one  illustration," 
said  the  general  secretary  of  the  United  Society  of  Boiler- 
makers, to  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor,  "  we  had  a  case 

1  The  Trade  Unionist  feeling  against  men  who  work  "under  price"  is 
expressed  in  the  following  quotation  from  the  Amended  General  Laws  of  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Cordwainers  (London,  1867),  one  of  the  most  ancient 
of  unions  : — 

"  A  scab  is  to  his  trade  what  a  traitor  is  to  his  country,  and  though  both 
may  be  useful  to  one  party  in  troublesome  times,  when  peace  returns  they  are 
detested  alike  by  all  ;  so  when  help  is  wanted  a  scab  is  the  last  to  contribute 
assistance,  and  the  first  to  grasp  a  benefit  he  never  labored  to  procure  ;  he  cares 
only  for  himself,  but  he  sees  not  beyond  the  extent  of  a  day ;  and  for  momentary 
and  worthless  approbation  would  betray  friends,  family,  and  country.  In  short, 
he  is  a  traitor  on  a  small  scale— he  first  sells  the  journeymen  and  is  himself  after- 
wards sold  in  his  turn  by  his  master,  until  at  last  he  is  despised  by  both  and 
deserted  by  all.  He  is  an  enemy  to  himself,  to  the  present  age,  and  to  posterity/' 


208  Trade  Union  Function 

at  Hartlepool  a  short  time  since,  where  a  vessel  was  in  for 
repairing,  and  the  men  knew  that  the  vessel  was  in  a  hurry, 
and  thought  there  was  a  very  good  chance  to  get  an  advance 
in  their  wages,  so  they  went  to  their  foreman,  and  made  a 
demand  for  2s.  a  week  advance.  The  foreman,  knowing  the 
arrangement  between  our  association  and  the  employers' 
association,  refused  to  give  the  advance,  and  at  once  wired  to 
me  at  Newcastle,  and  by  the  orders  of  the  council  I  sent  back 
to  say  that  the  employer  was  to  give  the  men  the  advance 
as  asked  for,  because  we  did  not  want  to  stop  the  work,  as 
the  ship  was  in  a  hurry,  and  we  wanted  to  get  her  off.  The 
employer  gave  the  men  the  advance  as  asked  for,  and  we  at 
once  sent  to  the  firm  requesting  the  firm  to  tell  us  the 
amount  of  money  they  had  paid  to  the  men  as  advances  of 
wages  on  that  job.  When  the  job  was  completed  those 
particulars  and  details  were  sent  to  us  at  Newcastle,  and  also 
the  names  of  the  men  who  were  engaged  upon  the  job,  and 
who  had  made  the  demand.  As  soon  as  that  was  done  our 
council  ordered  the  members  who  received  the  money  to 
refund  that  again  to  the  Society,  and  we  sent  a  cheque  from 
the  head  office  to  that  firm  equal  to  the  amount  of  the 
advances  given."  l  In  another  case  men  knowing  that  their 
employer  was  under  a  time  limit  for  the  completion  of  a 
ship  made  a  sudden  demand  for  a  rise.  Precisely  the  same 
action  was  taken  by  the  union,  and  the  men  were  also  fined 
"  for  dishonorable  behaviour  to  employer  under  contract  to 
deliver." 

1  Royal  Commission  on  Labor,  Group  A,  Question  20,718.  The  frequency 
with  which  this  disciplinary  power  is  exercised  may  be  judged  from  an  extract 
from  the  Monthly  Report  for  May  1897,  referring  only  to  a  single  district.  The 
list  is  not  usually  published. 

"The  following  members  have  been  dealt  with  by  the  committee  during 
April  : — 

F.  F.,  foreman,  holding  two  jobs  at  Heyes,  405. 

T.  B.,  rivetter,  doing  plater's  work,  IDs. 

E.  T.,  plater,  neglecting  his  work  through  drinking,  los. 

J.  J.,  rivetter,  doing  plater's  work,  2OS. 

H.  R.,  excessive  overtime,  305. 

T.  C.,  using  abusive  language  to  Strike  Secretary,  IDS. 

R.  D.,  using  disgusting  and  obscene  language  to  Mr.  W.  H.,  foreman,  ios,M 


Tke  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          209 


In  the  world  of  modern  industry  this  submission  of  the 
personal  judgment  to  the  Common  Rule  extends  far  beyond 
the  range  of  those  who,  by  Trade  Union  membership, 
may  be  considered  to  have  agreed  to  forego  an  individual 
decision.  When  the  associated  employers  in  any  trade 
conclude  an  agreement  with  the  Trade  Union,  the  Common 
Rule  thus  arrived  at  is  usually  extended  by  the  employers, 
as  a  matter  of  course,  to  every  workman  in  their  establish- 
ments, whether  or  not  he  is  a  member  of  the  union.1  This 
universal  application  of  a  collective  bargain  to  workmen 
who  have  neither  personally  nor  by  representatives  taken 
any  part  in  it,  is  specially  characteristic  of  the  Sliding  Scale. 
In  the  ironworks  of  the  North  and  Midlands  the  awards 
of  the  accountants  engaged  by  the  joint  committees  of 
employers  and  workmen  habitually  govern  every  wage 
contract  in  the  establishments  concerned,  however  distaste- 
ful the  whole  proceeding  may  be  to  a  particular  section  of 
workmen.  The  position  of  the  South  Wales  coalminers  is 
even  more  striking.  Not  a  third  of  the  120,000  men  are 
even  professedly  members  of  any  Trade  Union,  or  in  any  way 
represented  in  the  negotiations,  and  of  the  organised  work- 
men a  considerable  proportion,  forming  three  separate  unions, 
each  covering  a  distinct  district,  expressly  refused  to  agree 
to  the  1893  Sliding  Scale,  and  withdrew  their  representatives 
from  the  joint  committee.  Nevertheless,  the  whole  of  the 
120,000  men,  with  infinitesimal  special  exceptions,  find 
their  wages  each  pay-day  automatically  determined  by  the 
accountant's  award.  In  this  case  the  associated  employers, 
in  alliance  with  a  minority  of  the  workmen,  enforce,  upon 

1  This  practice  has  recently  received  authoritative  official  confirmation.  Certain 
boot  manufacturers  in  Bristol  and  Northampton,  whilst  holding  themselves  bound 
to  give  to  members  of  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  the  terms 
specified  in  the  collective  agreements,  claimed  the  right  to  pay  what  they  liked  to 
the  non-unionists  they  employed.  On  the  issue  being  referred,  at  the  instance  of 
the  Trade  Union,  to  the  Permanent  Secretary  of  the  Board  of  Trade  as  umpire, 
he  decided  that  the  decisions  of  the  Local  Boards  were,  unless  expressly  re- 
stricted, applicable  to  unionists  and  non-unionists  alike,  although  the  latter  were 
in  no  way  parties  to  the  agreement.  See  Award  of  6th  May  1896,  in  Labour 
Gazette,  May  1896. 

VOL.  I  P 


2io  Trade  Union  Function 

an  apathetic  or  dissentient  majority,  under  pain  of  exclusion 
from  the  industry  or  exile  from  the  district,  a  method  of 
remuneration  and  rates  of  payment  which  are  fiercely 
resented  by  many  of  them.  In  instances  of  this  kind  it  is 
the  employers  who  are  the  instruments  of  coercion.  In 
other  industries  we  find  the  Trade  Union,  acting  in  alliance 
with  the  Employers'  Association,  putting  its  own  forms  of 
pressure  on  dissentient  employers,  who  refuse  to  join  the 
association,  or  to  conform  to  the  arrangements  agreed  to 
by  the  industry  as  a  whole.  The  records  of  the  local 
boards  in  the  boot  and  shoe  trade  contain  many  appeals 
from  the  representatives  of  the  Associated  Employers  to  the 
National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives,  in  which  the 
union  is  incited  to  use  all  its  influence  to  compel  rival  firms 
to  conform  to  the  trade  agreements.  Here  a  majority  of 
workmen,  at  the  instance  of,  and  in  alliance  with  a  majority 
of  employers,  practically  force  a  minority  of  both  masters 
and  men  to  accept  the  Common  Rules  which  have  com- 
mended themselves  to  the  main  body  of  the  trade.  In 
short,  experience  shows  that  any  successful  attempt  to 
arrange  common  terms  in  a  highly  -  developed  modern 
industry,  inevitably  leads,  however  "  voluntary "  may  be 
the  basis  of  the  associations  concerned,  to  a  virtually  com- 
pulsory acquiescence  in  the  same  terms,  if  not  throughout 
the  whole  trade,  at  any  rate  by  many  firms  and  many  work- 
men who  have  in  no  sense  willingly  agreed  to  them. 

This  compulsion  takes  a  more  obvious  form  when  it  is  a 
question  of  providing  the  cost  of  the  machinery  by  which  the 
common  arrangements  are  made  and  applied.  In  the  South 
Wales  coalfield,  where,  as  we  have  seen,  the  Silding  Scale  is 
practically  universal,  a  compulsory  deduction  of  sixpence 
per  annum  is  made  by  the  employers  from  the  earnings  of 
about  40,000  men,  whether  or  not  they  individually  agree 
with  the  Sliding  Scale,  or  are  members  of  any  Trade  Union. 
In  the  Rhondda  Valley,  and  in  a  few  other  districts,  the 
compulsion  goes  a  step  farther.  The  employers  com- 
pulsorily  deduct  a  few  pence  per  month  from  their  work- 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          2  i  i 

icn's  earnings,  as  the  contribution  to  the  Trade  Union.      A 
irtain  agreed   percentage  is  retained   by  the  employer  and 
lis  clerks  for  their  trouble,  and   the  balance  is  handed  over 
the  agents  of  the  men's  unions.      By  far  the  largest  and 
lost  important  miners'  union  in   South   Wales  has  no  other 
ibscription    than    this    compulsory   deduction    in    the   em- 
ployer's   pay    office,    and    is    without     any    lodges,    branch 
officials,  or  other  organised   machinery.      To  all  intents  and 
purposes,  therefore,  Trade   Union   membership,  summed   up, 
as  it  is,  in   this  enforced   contribution  to  maintain   officials 
with  whom   the   employers  can   negotiate,  is,  over   a   large 
part  of  the  South  Wales  coalfield,  absolutely  compulsory.1 

But  whilst  the  compulsory  Trade  Unionism  of  the 
South  Wales  coalfields,  as  enforced  by  the  employers, 
extends  to  the  collective  arrangements,  and  to  payment 
for  their  cost,  it  makes  no  provision  for  ensuring  that  the 
apathetic  or  dissentient  workers  shall  have  any  opportunity 
of  expressing  their  desires,  or  of  taking  any  part  in  con- 
trolling their  own  side  of  the  business.  As  most  of  the 
men  from  whom  the  Sliding  Scale  pence  are  deducted  are 
not  even  nominally  on  the  roll  of  any  Trade  Union,  they 
are  never  troubled  to  vote  on  any  question,  and  the  work- 
ing-men members  on  the  Sliding  Scale  committee,  repre- 
senting the  small  minority  of  men  on  the  books  of  the 

1  A  similar  compulsory  membership  characterises  the  manufactured  iron 
trade.  The  Midland  Iron  and  Steel  Wages  Board  decided  that  employers  should 
compulsorily  collect  from  all  their  operatives  the  contribution  due  in  respect  of 
the  men's  share  of  the  Board's  expenses.  Some  employers  neglected  to  do  this, 
and  on  complaint  made  by  the  Operatives'  Secretary,  the  Chairman  of  the  Board 
held  that  all  employers  were  bound  to  make  the  deduction  (Ironworkers'  Journal, 
March  1895).  The  North  of  England  Manufactured  Iron  Board  adopts  the 
same  practice.  The  Truck  Act  of  1896  forbids  any  such^  deduction,  and,  in 
order  to  enable  ilTEo-bu  .lunlinuud,  Mr.  Trow,  the  Operatives'  Secretary,  moved 
and  carried  a  resolution  that  the  Home  Secretary  should  be  asked  to  make  an 
order  excluding  their  trade  from  the  scope  of  the  Act  (Ironworkers'  Journal, 
March  1897).  The  Midland  Board  unanimously  joined  in  the  application  on 
the  express  ground,  as  stated  by  the  Chairman,  that  the  Act  "  might  have  the 
effect  of  preventing  them  deducting  the  contributions  of  the  men  to  the  Wages 
Board"  (Iromvorker?  Journal,  April  1897).  It  will  be  interesting  to  see 
whether  the  Home  Secretary  extends  his  sanction  to  the  principle  of  compulsory 
contribution,  by  complying  with  the  request,  and  issuing  an  order  exempting 
the  whole  trade  from  the  Truck  Act. 


212  Trade  Union  Function 

several  unions,  conclude  such  agreements  with  the  employers, 
and  make  such  disposition  of  the  compulsory  deductions,  as 
seem  best  in  their  own  eyes,  or  in  those  of  their  immediate 
constituents.  We  have,  in  fact,  in  this  remarkable  case, 
an  instance  of  collective  administration  without  democratic 
control.  In  another  case  in  the  same  industry,  where 
collective  action  and  compulsory  payment  is  enforced  by 
the  law,  provision  is  at  least  made  for  a  ballot  to  be  taken. 
We  have  described  elsewhere l  how  long  and  persistently 
the  Miners'  Trade  Unions  have  fought  to  obtain  the  right 
to  have  their  own  agent  at  the  pit  mouth,  to  see  that  their 
members  are  not  defrauded  in  the  computation  of  their 
tonnage  earnings  ;  and  we  have  also  pointed  out  how  in- 
valuably these  checkweighers  have  served  as  union  officials.2 
By  the  Coal  Mines'  Regulation  Act  of  1887  it  was  enacted 
that,  whenever  a  mere  majority  of  the  workers  in  any  coal 
pit,  to  be  ascertained  by  a  ballot  vote,  decided  to  appoint  a 
checkweigher,  the  amount  of  his  wages  should  be  shared 
among  all  the  workers  in  the  pit  who  were  paid  according 
to  the  weight  of  coal  gotten,  and  that  it  should  be  com- 
pulsorily  deducted  from  their  earnings,  whether  they  voted 
for  the  appointment  or  against  it. 

More  generally,  however,  it  is  left  to  the  Trade  Union 
to  take  such  steps  as  it  can  to  enforce  the  common  trade 
agreements,  and  to  collect  for  itself  the  expenses  involved. 
This  may  be  effected  in  two  ways.  Following  the  example 
of  the  South  Wales  Coal-owners,  the  Trade  Union  may 
enforce,  throughout  the  whole  trade,  an  agreement  concluded 
between  a  section  of  the  employers  and  the  employed, 
levying  a  compulsory  tax  for  the  purpose  upon  all  persons 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  289,  453. 

2  Among  the  amendments  of  the  law  now  sought  by  the  Miners'  Federation 
is  one  enabling  the  hewers  in  any  mine  to  appoint  an  assistant  checkweigher,  at 
the  expense  of  the  whole  pit,  to  act  whenever  "  the  said  checkweigher  is  acting  in 
any  other  capacity  for  or  on  behalf  of  the  workmen  of  the  colliery."     "What 
they  wanted   to   do,"   explained   the   Yorkshire   representatives   at  the    Miners' 
Conference  in  1896,  "was  to  make  it  so  that  the  men  employed  at  any  colliery 
could  appoint  an  assistant  checkweigher  to  look  after  the  work  when  the  weigher 
was  away  on  association  business." 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          2 1 3 

at  work.  Thus  the  old  close  corporation  of  Dublin  Coopers, 
whilst  allowing  strangers  to  work,  does  not  admit  them  to 
membership,  but  insists  that  they  shall  obey  all  the  regula- 
tions of  the  union,  and  contribute  weekly  to  its  funds  so 
long  as  they  work  in  the  town.  But  this  "  taxation  without 
representation  "  is  alien  to  working  class  sentiment,  and  the 
almost  universal  practice  of  Trade  Unionism  is  to  expect 
every  member  of  the  trade  to  bear  his  share,  not  only  in  the 
cost  of  its  administration,  but  also  in  the  work  of  its  govern- 
ment. "  We  contend,"  declare  the  Flint  Glass  Makers, 
"that  it  is  the  imperative  duty  of  men  who  live  by  a  trade 
to  support,  protect,  and  keep  it  in  a  respectable  condition. 
Men  who  refuse  to  subscribe  to  the  funds  of  a  Trade  Union 
never  can  be  looked  upon  by  those  who  are  members  of 
such  a  union  with  that  feeling  of  satisfaction  and  respect 
which  makes  one  happy  in  the  thought  that  unity  of  action 
is  the  aim  of  all  for  the  good  of  each  other."  T  Hence  we 
have,  not  only  compulsory  acceptance  of  the  trade  customs 
but  also  compulsory  membership  of  the  Trade  Union  con- 
cerned. In  old  days,  when  any  Trade  Union  action  was 
a  criminal  offence,  this  compulsion  easily  passed  into  per- 
sonal violence.2  But  British  Trade  Unionists  now  content 
themselves  with  the  more  peaceful  method  practised  by  the 
employers.  An  employer  habitually  refuses  to  engage  any 
workman  who  does  not  agree  to  his  workshop  rules,  or  to  those 
adopted  by  the  employers'  association.  In  the  same  way, 
the  Trade  Unionist  will,  if  he  can,  refuse  to  accept  work  in 
an  establishment  where  he  is  obliged  to  associate  with  non- 
unionists  ;  "  working  beside  a  non-unionist,"  say  the  Flint 

1  Address  of  Central  Committee,  Flint  Glass  Makers'  Magazine,  May  1889. 

2  In  the   History  of  Trade    Unionism  we  have  described   the  practice  of 
"rattening,"  for  which  some  of  the  Sheffield  trade  clubs  were,  up  to  1867,  un- 
happily notorious.      In  the  early  part  of  the  century  the  trade  clubs  of  Dublin 
and  Glasgow  had  an  equally  evil  reputation  for  personal  violence  (see  History  of 
Trade   Unionism,  pp.    3,  31,   79,   149,  154,  242).     With   the  growth  of  legal 
freedom  for  Trade  Unions  to  employ  peaceful,  and  really  more  effective,  sanctions, 
this  resort  to  summary  lynch  law  has  died   out.      We  know  personally  of  no 
instance  in  which,  during  the  present  generation,  physical  violence  has  been  used 
to  compel  Trade  Union  membership. 


214  Trade  Union  Function 

Glass  Makers,  "  is  bad  enough  to  a  man  of  brain  and 
principle,  without  having  to  suffer  the  indignity  of  being 
compelled  to  assist  him  in  his  labor.  .  .  .  This  being  so 
we  do  not  hesitate  to  say  that  before  an  employer  engages 
a  unionist,  he  ought  to  clear  all  the  non-unionists  off  the 
premises.  Where  we  have  demanded  this,  it  has  been 
done."  This  is  put  even  more  definitely  by  the  Coal- 
miners.  The  minutes  of  the  Derbyshire  Miners  record,  for 
instance,  under  date  of  1892,  "that  this  Executive  Com- 
mittee recommend  our  members,  where  the  majority  are 
union  men,  to  use  every  legal  effort  to  induce  others  to 
join,  and  failing  this  we  advise  our  members  neither  to 
work  nor  ride  with  them,  but  that  due  notice  of  their 
intention  to  take  such  actions  be  given  to  the  management 
in  each  case  before  being  put  into  practice."  l 

There  is  a  strange  delusion  in  the  journalistic  mind  that 
this  compulsory  Trade  Unionism,  enforced  by  refusal  to  work 
with  non-unionists,  is  a  modern  device,  introduced  by  the 
"New  Unionists"  of  1889.  Thus  Mr.  Lecky  states  as  a 
fact 2  that  the  establishment  of  monopolies,  and  the  exclusion, 
"  often  by  gross  violence  and  tyranny,"  of  "  non-unionists 
from  the  trades  they  can  influence "  is  specially  marked 
"among  the  New  Unionists."  But  any  student  of  Trade 
Union  annals  knows  that  the  exclusion  of  non-unionists  is, 
on  the  contrary,  coeval  with  Trade  Unionism  itself,  and  that 
the  practice  is  far  more  characteristic  of  its  older  forms  than 
of  any  society  formed  in  the  present  generation.  The  trade 
clubs  of  handicraftsmen  in  the  eighteenth  century  would 
have  scouted  the  idea  of  allowing  any  man  to  work  at  their 
trade  who  was  not  a  member  of  the  club.  And  at  the 

1  Minutes  of  Executive  Meeting,  Derbyshire  Miners'  Association,  July  1892. 
It  is  an  incident  of  this  refusal,  on  the  part  of  the  employer  or  on  that  of  the 
wage-earner,  to  consent  to  work  with  persons  of  whose  conduct  he  disapproves, 
that  employers  seek  to  insist  on  "  character  notes,"  workmen  classify  firms  into 
"fair"   and    "unfair,"   and   the   associations  on   both   sides   circulate   to    their 
members    "blacklists"  of  the  men  who  have  made  themselves   objectionable, 
towards  the  employers  in  the  one  case,  and  towards  their  fellow  workmen  in  the 
other. 

2  Democracy  and  Liberty ',  vol.  ii.  p.  348. 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          2 1 5 

present  day  it  is  especially  in  the  old-fashioned  and  long- 
established  unions  that  we  find  the  most  rigid  enforce- 
ment of  membership.  Among  the  Coalminers  it  is  the 
men  of  Northumberland,  Durham,  and  the  West  Riding 
of  Yorkshire,  strongly  combined  for  a  whole  generation, 
who  have  set  the  fashion  of  absolutely  refusing  to  "ride" 
(descend  in  the  cage)  with  non-unionists.1  In  the  best 
organised  industries  indeed,  whether  great  or  small,  such  as 
the  Boilermakers,  Flint  Glass  Makers,  Tape-sizers,  or  StufT- 
pressers — the  very  aristocracy  of  "  Old  Unionists  " — the 
compulsion  is  so  complete  that  it  ceases  to  be  apparent.  No 
man  not  belonging  to  the  union  ever  thinks  of  applying  for 
a  situation,  or  would  have  any  chance  of  obtaining  one.  It 
is,  in  fact,  as  impossible  for  a  non-unionist  plater  or  rivetter 
to  get  work  in  a  Tyneside  shipyard,  as  it  is  for  him  to  take 
a  house  in  Newcastle  without  paying  the  rates.  This  silent 
and  unseen,  but  absolutely  complete  compulsion,  is  the  ideal 
of  every  Trade  Union.  It  is  true  that  here  and  there  an 
official  of  an  incompletely  organised  trade  may  protest  to 
the  public,  or  before  a  Royal  Commission,  that  his  members 
have  no  desire  that  any  workman  should  join  the  union 
except  by  his  own  free  will.  But,  however  bond  fide  may 
be  these  expressions  by  individuals,  we  invariably  see  such 
a  union,  as  soon  as  it  secures  the  adhesion  of  a  majority  of 
its  trade,  adopting  the  principle  of  compulsory  membership, 

1  For  an  extreme  instance  of  this  boycott  of  non-unionists,  see  the  remarkable 
letter  of  William  Crawford,  the  leader  of  the  Durham  miners,  given  in  full,  at 
p.  280  of  the  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  and  written,  we  believe,  about  1870. 
"  Regard  them,"  said  Crawford,  "  as  unfit  companions  for  yourselves  and  your 
sons,  and  unfit  husbands  for  your  daughters.  Let  them  be  branded,  as  it  were, 
with  the  curse  of  Cain,  as  unfit  to  mingle  in  ordinary,  honest,  and  respectable 
society."  But  this  extension  of  the  ostracism  from  the  workplace  to  the  home, 
from  industrial  relations  to  social  life,  is  repugnant  to  British  working-class  senti- 
ment, and  has  never  extensively  prevailed.  However  illogical  may  be  the  dis- 
tinction, there  is  a  general  feeling,  now  spreading,  we  think,  to  other  classes  of 
society,  that  it  is  inexpedient  to  extend  social  ostracism  beyond  the  sphere  of 
the  offence.  Business  men  habitually  deal  with  others  of  known  bad  character  in 
private  life,  so  long  as  their  commercial  dealings  are  unobjectionable.  On  the 
other  hand,  English  society  does  not  refuse  to  meet  at  dinner  statesmen  of  good 
private  character,  whose  public  acts  it  deems  in  the  last  degree  unscrupulous. 
The  more  logical  policy  advocated  by  Crawford  is  regarded  as  fanaticism. 


216  Trade  Union  Function 

and  applying  it  with  ever  greater  stringency  as  the  strength 
of  the  organisation  increases. 

Whatever  we  may  think  of  these  various  forms  of  com- 
pulsion, it  is  important  to  note  that  they  are  in  no  way 
inconsistent  with  the  old  ideal  of  "  freedom  of  contract  " — 
the  legal  right  of  every  individual  to  make  such  a  bargain 
for  the  purchase  or  sale  of  labor  as  he  may  think  most 
conducive  to  his  own  interest, — and  that  they  are,  in  fact, 
a  necessary  incident  of  that  legal  freedom. 

When  an  employer,  or  every  employer  in  a  district,  makes 
the  Sliding  Scale  a  condition  of  the  engagement  of  any  work- 
man, the  dissentient  minority  are  "  free  "  to  refuse  such  terms. 
They  may,  in  the  alternative,  break  up  their  homes  and  leave 
the  district,  or  learn  another  trade.  The  wage-earners  can- 
not be  denied  a  similar  freedom.  When  a  workman  chooses 
to  make  it  a  condition  of  his  acceptance  of  employment 
from  a  given  firm,  that  he  shall  not  be  required  to  asso- 
ciate with  colleagues  whom  he  dislikes,  he  is  but  exercis- 
ing his  freedom  to  make  such  stipulations  in  the  bargaining 
as  he  thinks  conducive  to  his  own  interest.  The  employer 
is  "  free  "  to  refuse  to  engage  him  on  these  terms,  and  if  the 
vast  majority  of  the  workmen  are  of  the  same  mind,  he  is 
"  free  "  to  transfer  his  brains  and  his  capital  to  another  trade, 
or  to  leave  the  district.  But  to  any  one  not  obsessed  by 
this  conception  of  "  freedom,"  it  will  be  obvious  that  a  mere 
legal  right  to  refuse  particular  conditions  of  employment  is 
no  safeguard  against  compulsion.  Where  practically  all  the 
competent  workmen  in  an  industry  are  strongly  combined, 
an  isolated  employer,  not  supported  by  his  fellow  capitalists, 
finds  it  absolutely  impossible  to  break  away  from  the  "  custom 
of  the  trade."  The  isolated  workman  who  objects  to  Trade 
Unionism  finds  himself  in  the  same  predicament.  The  coal- 
hewer  in  a  Northumberland  village  has  no  more  real  freedom 
of  choice  as  to  whether  or  not  he  will  join  the  union  than  a 
Glamorganshire  miner  has  about  working  under  the  Sliding 
Scale.  The  workmen's  case  for  Trade  Unionism  and  the 
employers'  case  against  it  both  proceed  on  the  same  assump- 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          2 1 7 

tion.1  Wherever  the  economic  conditions  of  the  parties  concerned 
are  unequal,  legal  freedom  of  contract  merely  enables  the 
superior  in  strategic  strength  to  dictate  the  terms.  Collective 
Bargaining  does  not  get  rid  of  this  virtual  compulsion  :  it 
merely  shifts  its  incidence.  Where  there  is  no  combination 
of  any  kind,  the  strategic  weakness  of  the  individual  wage- 
earner,  unable  to  put  a  reserve  price  on  his  labor,  forces 
him  to  accept  the  lowest  possible  terms.  When  the  work- 
men combine  the  balance  is  redressed,  and  may  even  incline, 
as  against  the  isolated  employer,  in  favor  of  the  wage-earner. 
If  the  employers  meet  combination  by  combination,  the  com- 
pulsion exercised  upon  individual  capitalists  or  individual 
wage-earners  may  become  so  irresistible  as  to  cease  to  be 
noticed.  In  the  most  perfected  form  of  Collective  Bargaining, 
compulsory  membership  becomes  as  much  a  matter  of  course 
as  compulsory  citizenship. 

If,  indeed,  we  examine  more  closely  the  common  argu- 
ments against  this  virtual  compulsion,  we  shall  see  that  the 
customary  objection  is  not  directed  against  the  compulsion 
itself,  but  only  against  the  persons  by  whom  it  is  exercised, 
or  the  particular  form  that  it  takes.  The  ordinary  middle- 
class  man,  without  economic  training,  is  wholly  unconscious 
of  there  being  any  coercion  in  an  employer  autocratically 
deciding  how  he  will  conduct  "  his  own  business." 2  But  the 
very  notion  of  the  workmen  claiming  to  decide  for  themselves 
under  what  conditions  they  will  spend  their  own  working 
days  strikes  him  as  subversive  of  the  social  order.  The 
ardent  Trade  Unionist,  on  the  other  hand,  resents  the 
"  tyranny "  of  the  employer's  workshop  rules,  but  sees  no 
harm  in  a  strong  union  relentlessly  enforcing  its  will  on  the 
capitalists,  without  deigning  to  consult  with  them  beforehand. 

1  This  assumption  is  examined  in  detail  in  our  chapter  on  "The  Higgling  of 
the  Market." 

2  "  The  capitalists  or  master  class  .   .   .  think  the  internal  arrangements  of 
their  establishments,  hours,  mode  of  payment  or  contract  no  more  the  affairs  of 
the  public  than  the  routine  of  a  man's  own  household." — "  Trade  Unions  and  their 
Tendencies,"  by  Edmund  Potter,  F.R.S.,  Social  Science  Association  Transactions, 
1860,  p.  755. 


2i8  Trade  Union  Function 

The  modern  compromise  between  these  diametrically  opposite 
views,  and  one  now  attracting  a  growing  share  of  public 
approval,  is  the  settlement  of  the  conditions,  neither  by  the 
workmen  nor  by  the  employers,  but  by  collective  agreement 
between  them.  It  is  this  feeling  that  accounts  for  the  ever- 
increasing  favor  for  Boards  of  Conciliation  and  Arbitration 
and  joint  committees  of  all  sorts.  Public  opinion,  that  is  to 
say,  accepts  as  inevitable  the  submission  of  the  individual  to 
the  Common  Rule,  and  seeks  merely  to  ensure  that  this 
submission  should  be  based  upon  due  representation  of  the 
persons  directly  concerned.  The  most  fervent  advocates  of 
this  Collective  Bargaining  between  the  representatives  of 
employers  and  employed  welcome,  in  the  interests  of  In- 
dustrial Peace,  the  application  of  these  collective  agreements 
over  whole  districts  of  an  industry,  and  for  specified  long 
terms,  though  this  necessarily  involves  the  compulsory 
acquiescence  of  individual  firms  and  individual  workmen 
who  would  have  preferred  to  make  separate  bargains.  And 
thus  we  come,  step  by  step,  to  the  remarkable  proposal  of 
the  Chairman  of  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor,  the  Duke 
of  Devonshire,  himself  a  great  employer,  concurred  in  by 
seven  other  eminent  members,  that  Trade  Unions  and 
Employers'  Associations,  extending  over  whole  trades,  should 
be  encouraged  to  become  definitely  incorporated  bodies, 
expressly  authorised  to  conclude  collective  agreements  for 
their  constituents,  and  empowered  to  secure  the  compliance 
of  all  their  members  with  these  new  trade  laws  by  legally 
enforcible  penalties,  "  every  member  of  a  (duly  registered) 
association  being  during  membership  held  to  be  under  a 
contract  with  the  association  for  observance  of  the  collective 
agreement,"  the  association  being  given  "  the  right  to  recover 
damages  from  those  of  its  members  who  infringed  the  collec- 
tive agreement."  l 

1  See  the  Report,  signed  by  the  Duke  of  Devonshire,  the  Right  Honorable 
Leonard  Courtney,  M.P.,  and  six  other  members,  C,  7421,  p.  117.  This  pro- 
posal is  further  examined  in  our  chapter  on  "The  Implications  of  Tiade 
Unionism." 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          2 1 9 

But  the  essential  reasonableness  of  English  public  opinion 
sets  limits  to  all  these  forms  of  legal  freedom  of  contract  and 
economic  compulsion,  whether  it  is  the  capitalist's  "  freedom 
of  enterprise,"  the  wage-earner's  "freedom  of  combination," 
or  the  freedom  of  representative  joint  committees  to  decide 
what  shall  be  the  customs  of  the  trade.  When  it  becomes 
obvious  that  individual  capitalists  are  using  their  strategic 
advantage  to  compel  the  wage-earners  to  accept  conditions 
patently  dangerous  to  life,  health,  or  character,  middle-class 
opinion  supports  legislation  to  curb  their  greed.  When  a 
group  of  workmen  strike  against  machinery,  or  to  enforce 
some  obviously  anti-social  regulation,  they  find  themselves 
deserted  by  the  general  body  of  Trade  Unionists,  frequently 
thwarted  by  other  members  of  their  trade,  and  even  con- 
demned by  the  executive  of  their  own  union.  And  when 
the  Duke  of  Devonshire  and  Mr.  Leonard  Courtney  pro- 
posed, in  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor,  to  give  increased 
power  of  trade  regulation  to  free  associations  of  employers 
and  employed,  they  were  met  by  the  objection  that  such 
joint  agreements  in  particular  trades  might  easily  become 
prejudicial  to  the  interests  of  other  industries  or  of  the  general 
body  of  consumers.  At  the  root  of  all  these  instinctive 
qualifications  of  logical  doctrines,  there  lies  a  half-conscious 
admission  that  neither  employers  nor  employed  are  morally 
free  to  ignore  the  interest  of  the  community  as  a  whole. 
This  reveals  to  us  an  inherent  shortcoming  of  every  attempt 
to  determine  the  conditions  of  industry  by  mere  contract 
between  capitalists  and  workmen.  Even  in  the  most  per- 
fected forms  of  Collective  Bargaining,  when  each  of  the 
parties  is  fully  represented,  and  the  agreement  arrived  at 
really  expresses  the  combined  desires  of  both,  there  is  no 
guarantee  that  the  terms  are  such  as  will  be  conducive  to 
the  welfare  of  the  community. 

We  have  left  to  the  last  what  is  usually  regarded  as  the 
capital  drawback  to  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining, 
even  in  its  most  perfect  development.  In  the  machinery 
adopted  by  the  Lancashire  Cotton  Operatives,  for  instance, 


22O  Trade  Union  Function 

there  is  no  provision  for  the  contingency  of  a  failure  to  come 
to  an  agreement.  In  such  a  contingency  the  bargaining 
simply  comes  to  an  end,  and  we  have  that  deliberate  collec- 
tive refusal  on  the  part  of  the  employers  to  give  work,  or 
on  the  part  of  the  operatives  to  accept  work,  which  is  known 
as  a  "  lock-out "  or  a  "  strike."  These  cessations  of  work 
are,  in  our  view,  necessarily  incidental  to  all  commercial 
bargaining  for  the  hire  of  labor,  whether  individual 
or  collective,  just  as  the  customer's  walking  out  of  the 
shop,  if  he  does  not  consent  to  the  shopkeeper's  price,  is 
incidental  to  retail  trade.1  This,  we  need  hardly  observe, 
is  a  very  different  matter  from  the  ignorant  assumption  that 
there  is  some  necessary  connection  between  strikes  and 
Trade  Unions.  We  have  already  noted  the  existence  of 
Trade  Unions  which  prefer  the  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance 
to  that  of  Collective  Bargaining,  and  do  not  therefore  engage 
in  strikes  at  all ;  and  we  shall  elsewhere  instance  Trade 
Union  organisations  whose  operation  is  confined  to  the 
Method  of  Legal  Enactment.  On  the  other  hand,  long 
before  a  Trade  Union  comes  into  existence  in  any  industry. 
Collective  Bargaining,  as  we  have  already  explained,  prevails 
in  a  more  or  less  elaborate  form  ;  and,  with  Collective  Bar- 
gaining, the  inevitable  resort  to  concerted  refusal  to  work. 
It  is  a  matter  of  simple  history  that  strikes  have  been  far 
more  numerous  in  industries  which  have  practised  Collective 
Bargaining  without  Trade  Unionism,  than  in  those  in  which 
durable  combinations  have  existed.2  The  influence  of  Trade 
Unions  on  strikes  is  indeed  exactly  similar  to  their  influence 
on  Collective  Bargaining.  The  elaboration  of  the  "  shop 

1  The  bitterest  opponents  of  Trade  Unionism  admit  this.      "  Strikes,  I  con- 
sider," said  a  leading  employer  in  1860,  "as  the  action  and  the  almost  inevitable 
result  of  commercial  bargaining  for  labor.      They  will  always  exist." — "Trade 
Unions  and  their  Tendencies,"  by  Edmund  Potter,  F.R.S.,  Social  Science  Associa- 
tion Transactions,  1860,  p.  75^. 

2  We   need    only  remind  the   reader  of  the   incessant   "  pit  strikes "  of  the 
Northumberland  and  other  coalfields  prior  to  the  miners'  organisation  in  per- 
manent Trade  Unions  ;  of  such  angry  insurrections  as  those  of  the  Luddites  in 
1811  and  the  "plug  riots"  of  1842;  and  of  the  perpetual  series  of  "shop  dis- 
putes "  that  still  go  on   among  those  handicrafts  which  have  not  advanced  in 
organisation  beyond  the  "shop  bargain." 


The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining          2  2 1 

bargain  "  into  the  local  "  working  rules,"  and  of  these  again 
into  the  national  agreement  has  naturally  been  accompanied 
by  a  similar  extension  of  the  "  shop  dispute,"  into  a  local 
strike,  and  of  this  again  into  a  general  stoppage  of  the 
industry.  In  this  connection  we  may  quote  the  Royal  Com- 
mission on  Labor,  "  that  when  both  sides  in  a  trade  are 
strongly  organised  and  in  possession  of  considerable  financial 
resources,  a  trade  conflict,  when  it  does  occur,  may  be  on  a 
very  large  scale,  very  protracted  and  very  costly.  But  just 
as  a  modern  war  between  two  great  European  States,  costly 
though  it  is,  seems  to  represent  a  higher  state  of  civilisation 
than  the  incessant  local  fights  and  border  raids  which  occur 
in  times  or  places  where  governments  are  less  strong  and 
centralised,  so,  on  the  whole,  an  occasional  great  trade  con- 
flict, breaking  in  upon  years  of  peace,  seems  to  be  preferable 
to  continued  local  bickerings,  stoppages  of  work,  and  petty 
conflicts."  * 

But  whether  or  not  we  accept  this  flattering  analogy, 
it  is  impossible  to  deny  that  the  perpetual  liability  to 
end  in  a  strike  or  a  lock-out  is  a  grave  drawback  to  the 
Method  of  Collective  Bargaining.  So  long  as  the  parties  to 
a  bargain  are  free  to  agree  or  not  to  agree,  it  is  inevitable 
that,  human  nature  being  as  it  is,  there  should  now  and  again 
come  a  deadlock,  leading  to  that  trial  of  strength  and  endur- 
ance which  lies  behind  all  bargaining.  We  know  of  no 
device  for  avoiding  this  trial  of  strength  except  a  deliberate 
decision  of  the  community  expressed  in  legislative  enact- 
ment. One  favourite  panacea,  incidentally  referred  to  in  our 
account  of  the  boot  and  shoe  trade — the  reference  of  the 
dispute  to  an  impartial  arbitrator — we  reserve  for  a  separate 
chapter. 

1  Fifth  and  Final  Report  of  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor,  1894,  C,  7421, 
p.  36.  Mr.  Lecky  echoes  this  report.  "  There  can  be  little  doubt  that  the 
largest,  wealthiest,  and  best-organised  Trade  Unions  have  done  much  to  diminish 
labor  conflicts." — Democracy  and  Liberty,  vol.  ii.  p.  355. 


CHAPTER    III 

ARBITRATION 

THE  essential  feature  of  arbitration  as  a  means  of  determin- 
ing the  conditions  of  employment  is  that  the  decision  is  not 
the  will  of  either  party,  or  the  outcome  of  negotiation  between 
them,  but  the  fiat  of  an  umpire  or  arbitrator.  It  is  dis- 
tinguished from  that  organised  negotiation  between  Trade 
Unions  and  Employers'  Associations  which  we  have  termed 
Collective  Bargaining,  in  that  the  result  is  not  arrived  at  by 
bargaining  at  all,  the  higgling  between  the  parties  being,  in 
fact,  expressly  superseded.  On  the  other  hand,  it  is  not 
Legal  Enactment,  though  it  bears  some  resemblance  to  this 
form,  because  the  award  is  not  obligatory  on  either  of  the 
parties.  Their  refusal  to  accept  it,  or  their  ceasing  to  obey 
it,  even  if  they  have  promised  to  do  so,  carries  with  it  no 
coercive  sanction. 

These  characteristics  of  arbitration,  as  a  method  of 
settling  the  conditions  of  employment,  come  to  the  front  on 
every  typical  occasion.  We  see  the  employers  and  workmen 
at  variance  with  each  other.  Negotiations,  more  or  less 
formally  carried  on,  proceed  up  to  a  point  at  which  a  dead- 
lock seems  inevitable.  To  avert  a  stoppage  of  the  industry, 
both  parties  agree  to  "  go  to  arbitration."  They  adopt  an 
impartial  umpire,  either  to  act  alone  or  with  assessors 
representing  each  side.  Each  party  then  prepares  an 
elaborate  "  case,"  which  is  laid  before  the  new  tribunal. 
Witnesses  are  called,  examined,  and  cross-examined.  The 


Arbitration  223 

umpire  asks  for  such  additional  information  as  he  thinks 
fit.  Throughout  the  proceedings  the  utmost  latitude  is 
allowed.  The  "  reference "  is  seldom  limited  to  particular 
alternatives,  or  expressed  with  any  precision.1  The  umpire, 
in  order  to  clear  up  points,  is  always  entering  into  conversa- 
tion with  the  parties.  Practically  no  argument,  however 
seemingly  irrelevant,  is  excluded ;  and  evidence  may  be 
given  in  support  of  claims  founded  on  the  most  diverse 
economic  theories.  Finally,  the  umpire  gives  his  award  in 
precise  terms,  but  usually  without  stating  either  the  facts 
which  have  influenced  him  or  the  assumptions  upon  which 
he  has  made  up  his  mind.  The  award — and  this  is  an 
essential  feature — carries  with  it  no  legal  sanction,  and  may 
at  any  moment  be  repudiated  or  quietly  ignored  by  any 
capitalist  or  workman.2 

1  Thus  the  operatives  may  be  asking  for  an  Eight  Hours'  Day,  the  dismissal 
"of  an  unjust  foreman,  and  the  abolition  of  sub-contracting,  whilst  the  employers 
urge  a  reduction  of  wages  and  the  more  regular  attendance  of  the  men.      The 
umpire's  award   may  include  any  or  all  of  these  points,  and   might  conceivably 
decide  all  in  favour  of  the  respective  claimants. 

2  A  list  of  the  principal  works  on  arbitration  will   be  found  at  p.  323  of  our 
History  of  Trade  Unionism.      Mention  should  have   been  made  among  them  of 
the  report  on  Industrial  Conciliation  and  Arbitration  prepared  by  Carroll  D. 
Wright  for  the  Massachusetts  Labor  Bureau  (Boston,  i8Si);  and  J.  S.  Jeans's 
Conciliation  and  Arbitration  in  Labour  Disputes  (London,  1894)  can  now  be 
added.     The  most  important  recent  publications  have  been  made  on  the  Conti- 
nent.    We  may  cite,  in  particular,  the  bulky  volume  of  the  French  "Office  du 
Travail,"  entitled  De  la  Conciliation  et  de  F  arbitrage  dans  les  Conflits  Collectifs 
entre  patrons  et  ouvriers  en  France  et  a  I'ttranger  (Paris,  1893)  »  the  numerous 
reports  and  pamphlets  by  Julien  Weiller  of  Mariemont,  Belgium  ;  and  Conseils  de 
Findustrie  et  du  travail  by  Charles   Morisseaux  (Brussels,  1890).     The  English 
experience   is  well  discussed  by   Dr.   von  Schulze-Gaevernitz   in  Zttm  Socialen 
Frieden  (Leipzig,  1890),  translated  as  Social  Peace  (London,  1893). 

The  student  should  note  that  there  has  been,  until  quite  recently,  no  clear 
distinction  drawn  between  Collective  Bargaining,  Conciliation,  and  Arbitration. 
Much  of  what  is  called  Arbitration  or  Conciliation  in  the  earlier  writings  on  the 
subject  amounts  to  nothing  more  than  organised  Collective  Bargaining.  Thus, 
the  classic  work  of  Mr.  Henry  Crompton  (Industrial  Conciliation,  London,  1876) 
describes,  as  "conciliation,"  the  typical  cases  in  which  representative  employers 
and  workmen  meet  to  bargain  on  behalf  of  the  trade.  The  Nottingham  hosiery 
board,  established  in  1860,  often  described  as  a  model  of  arbitration,  was,  in 
effect,  nothing  more  than  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining,  no  outsider  being 
present,  the  casting  vote  being  given  up,  and  the  decisions  being  arrived  at  by 
what  the  men  called  "  a  long  jaw."  In  1868  Mr.  Mundella  observed  in  a  lecture, 
"  It  is  well  to  define  what  we  mean  by  arbitration.  The  sense  in  which  we  use 
the  word  is  that  of  an  arrangement  for  open  and  friendly  bargaining  ...  in 


224  Trade  Union  Function 

Yet  arbitration  has  one  characteristic  feature  in  common 
with  the  higgling  of  employers  and  workmen  which  it  super- 
sedes. The  arbitrator's  award  is  a  general  ordinance,  which, 
in  so  far  as  it  is  accepted,  puts  an  end  to  Individual  Bargain- 
ing between  man  and  man,  and  thus  excludes,  from  influence 
on  the  terms  of  employment,  the  exigencies  of  particular 
workmen,  and  usually  also  those  of  particular  firms.  It 
establishes,  in  short,  like  Collective  Bargaining,  a  Common 
Rule  for  the  industry  concerned.  We  can  therefore  under- 
stand why  the  Trade  Unionists  from  1850  to  1876  so 
persistently  strove  for  arbitration,  and  so  eagerly  welcomed 
the  gradual  conversion  of  the  governing  classes  to  a  belief  in 
its  benefits.  At  a  time  when  the  majority  of  employers 
asserted  their  right  to  deal  individually  with  each  one  of 
their  "  hands,"  habitually  refused  even  to  meet  the  men's 
representatives  in  discussion,  and  sought  to  suppress  Col- 
lective Bargaining  altogether  by  the  use  of  ambiguous 
statutes  and  obsolete  law,  it  was  an  immense  gain  for  the 
Trade  Unions  to  get  their  fundamental  principle  of  a  Common 
Rule  adopted.1  During  the  last  twenty  years  arbitration  has 
greatly  increased  in  popularity  among  the  public,  and  each 
ministry  in  succession  prides  itself  on  having  attempted  to 
facilitate  its  application.  Whenever  an  industrial  war  breaks 
out,  we  have,  in  these  days,  a  widespread  feeling  among  the 
public  that  both  parties  should  voluntarily  submit  to  the 
decision  of  an  impartial  arbitrator.  But  however  convenient 
this  solution  may  be  to  a  public  of  consumers,  the  two 
combatants  seldom  show  any  alacrity  in  seeking  it,  and  can 

which  masters  and  men  meet  together  and  talk  over  their  common  affairs  openly 
and  freely." — Arbitration  as  a  Means  of  Preventing  Strikes,  by  A.  J.  Mundella 
(Bradford,  1868). 

1  Arbitration  was  accordingly  opposed  by  the  more  clear-sighted  of  the 
opponents  of  Trade  Unionism.  "Our  main  objection,"  said  one  of  the  leading 
critics,  "both  to  arbitration  and  conciliation,  as  palliatives  of  Unionism,  is  that 
they  sanction,  nay  necessitate,  the  continuance  of  the  system  of  combination,  as 
opposed  to  that  of  individual  competition.  ...  In  so  doing  we  lend  the 
authority  of  public  recognition  to  the  pestilent  principle  of  combination,  and 
sanction  the  substitution  of  an  artificial  mechanism  for  that  natural  organism 
which  Providence  has  provided  for  the  harmonious  regulation  of  industrial 
interests." — Trade  Unionism,  by  J^mes  Stirling  (Glasgow,  1869),  p.  50. 


Arbitration  225 

rarely  be  persuaded  to  agree  to  refer  their  quarrel  to  any 
outside  authority.  Although  arbitration  has  been  preached 
as  a  panacea  for  the  last  fifty  years,  the  great  majority  of 
"  captains  of  industry  "  still  resent  it  as  an  infringement  of 
their  right  to  manage  their  own  business,  whilst  the  leaders  of 
the  organised  workmen,  once  enthusiastic  in  its  favor,  now 
usually  regard  it  with  suspicion.  The  four  years,  1891-95,  saw, 
in  Great  Britain,  four  great  industrial  disputes  in  as  many 
leading  industries.  But  neither  in  cotton  manufacture  nor  in 
coal-mining,  neither  in  the  great  machine  industry  of  boot- 
making  nor  in  engineering,  could  the  capitalists  and  workmen 
agree  to  let  their  quarrels  be  settled  by  an  impartial  umpire. 
What  happened  in  each  of  these  instances — and  they  were 
typical  of  many  others — was  the  breaking  off  of  Collective 
Bargaining,  a  prolonged  stoppage  and  trial  of  endurance, 
ending,  not  in  arbitration  but  in  a  resumption  of  Collective 
Bargaining,  and  the  conclusion  of  a  fresh  agreement  under 
new  and  more  favorable  auspices. 

At  first  sight  this  disinclination  of  workmen  or  employers 
to  submit  their  claims  to  an  impartial  tribunal  appears  per- 
verse and  unreasonable.  Business  men,  it  is  said,  almost 
invariably  refer  disputes  between  themselves  to  more  or  less 
formal  arbitration,  and  would  never  dream  of  stopping  their 
own  industry,  or  drying  up  the  source  of  their  own  profits, 
merely  because  they  could  not  agree  upon  an  impartial 
umpire.  And  if  this  be  true  in  commercial  transactions, 
where  the  alternative  is  nothing  worse  than  an  action  at  law, 
how  much  stronger  the  need  must  seem  when  the  alternative 
may  easily  involve  the  bankruptcy  of  capitalists,  the  semi- 
starvation  of  thousands  of  operatives,  and  the  temporary 
paralysis,  if  not  the  permanent  injury,  of  an  important 
national  industry?  Unfortunately  this  taking  analogy, 
drawn  from  the  arbitration  between  business  firms,  rests  on 
the  old  confusion  between  interpreting  an  existing  agree- 
ment and  concluding  a  new  one.  Commercial  arbitrations 
are  invariably  concerned  with  relations  already  entered  into, 
either  by  existing  contracts  or  under  the  law  of  the  land. 
VOL.  I  Q 


226  Trade  Union  Function 

No  business  man  ever  dreams  of  submitting  to  arbitration 
the  terms  upon  which  he  shall  make  new  purchases  or  future 
sales.1  Arbitration  in  commercial  matters  is  therefore  strictly 
confined  to  questions  of  interpretation,  both  parties  resting 
their  claims  on  a  common  basis,  the  existence  of  which  is 
not  in  dispute  between  them.  Now,  issues  of  interpretation 
of  this  kind  are  incessantly  occurring  between  employers  and 
employed,  even  in  the  best-regulated  industries.  In  these 
cases,  as  we  shall  hereafter  point  out,  whilst  there  is  no  in- 
superable objection  to  arbitration,  there  is  no  real  necessity 
to  resort  to  it.  Nor  is  it  for  this  class  of  disputes  that 
arbitration  is  usually  proposed.  The  great  strikes  and  lock- 
outs which  paralyse  a  whole  industry  almost  invariably  arise 
not  on  issues  of  interpretation,  but  on  the  proposal  of  either 
workmen  or  employers  to  alter  the  terms  upon  which,  for 
the  future,  labor  shall  be  engaged. 

The  position  of  the  employers  who  object  to  the  fixing 
of  the  terms  of  the  wage  contract  by  the  fiat  of  an  arbitrator 
has,  from  the  first,  been  logical  and  consistent.  In  a  weighty 
article  which  appeared,  twenty  years  ago,  in  the  official  organ 
of  the  National  Association  of  Employers  of  Labor,  we  find 
the  case  stated  with  perfect  lucidity : — 

"  The  sphere  of  arbitration  in  trade  disputes  is  strictly 
and  absolutely  limited  to  cases  of  specific  contract,  where  the 
parties  differ  as  to  the  terms  of  the  contract,  and  are  willing, 
for  the  sake  of  agreement  and  an  honorable  fulfilment  of 
their  engagements,  to  submit  the  points  in  dispute  to 
competent  men  mutually  chosen.  Where  there  is  a  basis 
and  instrument  of  agreement  by  the  parties  to  which  they 

1  The  frequently  cited  "  Conseils  de  Prud'hommes "  of  France  (established 
first  at  Lyons  in  1808,  and  since  greatly  developed  in  all  industrial  centres)  are 
strictly  confined  to  the  settlement  of  disputes  arising  out  of  existing  contracts,  or 
(as  regards  minor  matters)  the  application  of  the  law.  In  no  case  do  they  presume 
to  fix  the  rate  of  wages  for  future  engagements.  They  are  indeed  merely  cheap  and 
convenient  legal  tribunals,  which  make  efforts  to  compose  a  dispute  before  pro- 
ceeding to  pronounce  judgment  upon  it.  For  a  useful  account  of  these  councils, 
see  E.  Thomas,  Les  Conseils  ties  Prud'1  homines  %  leur  Histoire  et  leur  Organisation 
(Paris,  1888).  We  understand  that  this  is  the  character  also  of  the  similar 
tribunals  which  exist  in  various  German  States  and  elsewhere. 


Arbitration  227 

wish  to  adhere,  and  on  which  arbiters  have  something 
tangible  to  decide  upon,  it  is  seldom  difficult  for  impartial 
men  to  elicit  an  adjustment  fair  and  equitable  to  both  sides. 
Arbitration  is  thus  constantly  of  use  in  business  matters  on 
which  differences  of  view  have  arisen,  and  is  as  applicable  to 
questions  between  workmen  and  employers  where  there  is  a 
specific  contract  to  be  interpreted  as  in  any  other  branch  of 
affairs.  It  is  better  than  going  to  law,  much  better  than 
running  away  from  the  contract,  striking,  coercing,  and  fall- 
ing into  civil  damages  or  criminal  penalties,  and  raising  on 
the  back  of  such  unfortunate  consequences  a  blatant  and 
endless  protest  against  '  the  labor  laws.'  But  cases  in  which 
there  are  specific  contracts  absolutely  define  the  sphere 
of  arbitration.  To  apply  the  term  '  arbitration  '  to  the  rate 
of  wages  for  the  future,  in  regard  to  which  there  is  no  ex- 
plicit contract  or  engagement,  and  all  the  conditions  of  which 
are  unknown  to  employers  and  employed,  is  the  grossest 
misnomer  that  can  be  conceived.  It  is  certain  that  neither 
workmen  nor  employers  could  be  bound,  nor  would  consent 
to  be  bound,  even  were  it  possible  to  bind  them,  by  such 
arbitrary  decrees  ;  and  that  the  law,  therefore,  can  never  give 
such  decrees  even  any  temporary  force,  unless  we  are  to  fall 
back  into  the  long  obsolete  tyranny  of  fixing  the  rate  of 
wages  by  Act  of  Parliament,  or  by  '  King  in  Council/  or 
by  '  Communal  Bureau  of  Public  Safety,'  or  whatever  the 
supreme  power  may  be."  1 

Thus,  from  the  employers'  point  of  view,  the  supersession 
of  the  higgling  of  the  market  by  the  fiat  of  an  arbitrator 
is,  on  its  economic  side,  as  indefensible  an  interference  with 
industrial  freedom  as  a  legal  fixing  of  the  rate  of  wages. 
But  an  arbitrator's  award  has  additional  disadvantages. 
A  law  would  at  any  rate  be  an  authoritative  settlement, 
which  disposed  of  the  question  beyond  dispute  or  cavil.  An 
arbitrator's  award,  on  the  other  hand,  even  if  it  is  accepted 
by  the  Trade  Union,  may  not  commend  itself  to  all  the 
workmen.  The  employers  who  accept  it  may  not  unnaturally 

1   Capital  and  Labour,  1 6th  June  1875. 


228  Trade  Union  Function 

feel  that  they  have  surrendered  their  own  freedom,  without 
securing  any  guarantee  that  the  workmen,  or  some  indispens- 
able sections  of  them,  will  not  promptly  commence  a  new 
attack  on  which  to  provoke  a  stoppage  of  the  industry.  A 
law,  moreover,  is  a  Common  Rule,  enforced  with  uniformity 
on  all  alike.  The  arbitrator's  award,  on  the  other  hand, 
binds  only  those  firms  and  those  workmen  who  were  parties 
to  it.  In  almost  all  industries  there  are  some  establishments, 
and  often  whole  districts,  which  remain  outside  the  employers' 
association,  and  in  which  masters  and  men  persist  in  conduct- 
ing their  businesses  in  their  own  way.  And  there  is  no 
guarantee  that  some  firms  will  not  break  away  from  the 
association,  and  join  the  ranks  of  these  unfettered  outsiders. 
If  the  arbitrator's  award  has  secured  better  terms  to  the 
operatives  than  the  masters  are  unanimously  willing  to 
concede,  the  good  and  honorable  employers  are  penalised 
by  their  virtue.  The  proceedings  of  the  "  Boards  of 
Conciliation  and  Arbitration  "  of  the  boot-making  industry 
contain  many  complaints  by  employers  that  the  awards  are 
not  enforced  on  rival  firms,  who  are  consequently  undercut- 
ting them  in  the  market.  If  our  factory  or  mines  legislation 
had  been  enforced  only  on  specified  good  employers,  and  had 
left  untouched  any  firm  who  objected  to  the  regulations,  so 
intolerable  an  injustice  would  quickly  have  led  to  a  repudiation 
of  the  whole  system. 

If  we  turn  from  the  employers  to  the  Trade  Unionists, 
we  find  a  steadily  increasing  disinclination  among  workmen 
to  agree  to  the  intervention  of  an  arbitrator  to  settle  the 
terms  of  a  new  wage  contract.  This  growing  antipathy l  to 

1  We  may  cite  as  evidence  of  this  antipathy  some  recent  declarations  made  in 
the  names  of  the  three  most  powerful  organisations  in  the  United  Kingdom.  It 
is  expressly  stated  (for  instance,  in  the  Derbyshire  Miners'  Executive  Council 
Minutes  of  the  2nd  of  June  1891)  that  it  was  the  idea  that  the  Royal  Commission 
on  Labor  was  intended  to  introduce  a  ' '  huge  arbitration  system  "  that  determined 
the  whole  Miners'  Federation  steadfastly  to  refuse  to  have  anything  to  do  with 
that  inquiry.  "  We  are  opposed  to  the  system  altogether,"  declared  Mr.  Mawdsley 
before  that  Commission  (Group  C,  Answer  776),  on  behalf  of  the  Lancashire 
cotton  operatives.  And  Mr.  Robert  Knight,  giving  evidence  on  behalf  of  the 
United  Society  of  Boilermakers  (Group  A,  Answer  20,833),  definitely  negatived 
the  idea  of  arbitration,  explaining  as  follows :  "I  speak  from  long  experience  of 


Arbitration  229 

arbitration  is,  we  think,  mainly  due  to  their  feeling  of 
uncertainty  as  to  the  fundamental  assumptions  upon  which 
the  arbitrator  will  base  his  award.  When  the  issue  is  whether 
the  "  standard  earnings  "  of  the  Lancashire  Cotton-spinners 
should  or  should  not  be  decreased  by  ten  per  cent,  there 
is  no  basis  accepted  by  both  parties,  except  the  vague 
admission  that  the  award  should  not  be  contrary  to  the 
welfare  of  the  community.  But  this  offers  no  guidance  to 
the  arbitrator.  Judge  Ellison,  for  instance,  acting  in  1879 
in  a  Yorkshire  coal -mining  case,  frankly  expressed  the 
perplexity  of  an  absolutely  open-minded  umpire.  "It  is 
[he  said]  for  (the  employers'  advocate}  to  put  the  men's  wages 
as  high  as  he  can.  It  is  for  (the  merits  advocate)  to  put  them 
as  low  as  he  can.  And  when  you  have  done  that  it  is  for 
me  to  deal  with  the  question  as  well  as  I  can  ;  but  on  what 
principle  I  have  to  deal  with  it  I  have  not  the  slightest  idea. 
There  is  no  principle  of  law  involved  in  it.  There  is  no 
principle  of  political  economy  in  it.  Both  masters  and  men 
are  arguing  and  standing  upon  what  is  completely  within  their 
rights.  The  master  is  not  bound  to  employ  labor  except 
at  a  price  which  he  thinks  will  pay  him.  The  man  is  not 
bound  to  work  for  wages  that  won't  assist  (subsist)  him  and 
his  family  sufficiently,  and  so  forth.  So  that  you  are  both 
within  your  rights  ;  and  that's  the  difficulty  I  see  in  dealing 
with  the  question."  * 

But  this  cold-blooded  elimination  of  everything  beyond 
the  legal  rights  of  the  parties  is  neither  usual  in  a  wages 
arbitration,  nor  acceptable  to  either  side.  Each  of  the  parties 
implicitly  rests  its  case  on  a  distinct  economic  assumption, 
or  even  series  of  assumptions,  not  accepted  by  the  other  side, 

the  working  of  this  large  organisation  that  I  represent  here  to-day,  and  I  say  that 
we  can  settle  all  our  differences  without  any  interference  on  the  part  of  Parliament 
or  anybody  else."  The  same  feeling  is  shared  by  smaller  societies.  "Our 
experience  of  arbitration,"  states  the  secretary  of  the  North  Yorkshire  and  Cleve- 
land (Ironstone)  Miners'  Association,  "  was  that  we  always  got  the  worst  of  it,  and 
so  since  1877  it  has  been  firmly  refused." — Joseph  Toyn,  in  Newcastle  leader 
"Extra"  on  Conciliation  in  Trade  Disputes  (Newcastle,  1894),  p.  9. 

1  Report  of  South  Yorkshire  Collieries  Arbitration  (Sheffield,  1879),  P-  49- 
The  umpire  was  the  Judge  of  the  Sheffield  County  Court. 


230  Trade  Union  Function 

and  often  not  expressly  stated.  The  employers  will  often 
hold  that,  in  order  to  secure  the  utmost  national  prosperity, 
wages  should  rise  and  fall  with  the  price  which  they  can 
obtain  for  their  product.  Or  it  may  be  urged  that  the  wage 
bill  must,  under  no  circumstances,  encroach  upon  the  parti- 
cular percentage  of  profit  assumed  to  be  necessary  to  prevent 
capital  from  leaving  the  trade.1  These  assumptions  would, 
at  one  time,  have  been  acquiesced  in  by  many  leading 
workmen,  although,  perhaps,  not  by  the  rank  and  file.  But 
during  the  last  twenty  years,  the  leaders  of  the  most  power- 
ful organisations  have  definitely  taken  up  the  view  that  con- 
siderations of  market  price  or  business  profit  ought,  in  the 
interests  of  the  community,  to  be  strictly  subordinated  to 
the  fundamental  question  of  "  Can  a  man  live  by  the  trade  ?  " 
It  is  urged  that  the  payment  of  "  a  living  wage  "  ought,  under 
all  circumstances,  to  be  a  "  first  charge  "  upon  industry,  taking 
precedence  even  of  rents  or  royalties,  and  of  the  hypothetical 
percentage  allowed  as  a  minimum  to  capital  in  the  worst 
times.  The  skilled  mechanic  moreover  will  claim  that  the 
length  of  his  apprenticeship  warrants  him  in  insisting,  like 
the  physician  or  the  barrister,  on  a  minimum  fee  for  his 
services  below  which  he  cannot  be  asked  to  descend.  The 
arbitrator's  award,  if  it  is  not  a  mere  "  splitting  the  difference," 
must  be  influenced  by  one  or  the  other  of  these  assumptions, 
either  as  a  result  of  the  argument  before  him,  or  as  the 
outcome  of  his  education  or  sympathies.  However  judicial 
he  may  be  in  ascertaining  the  facts  of  the  case,  the  relative 
importance  which  he  will  give  to  the  rival  assumptions  of 
the  parties  can  scarcely  fail  to  be  affected  by  the  subtle 

1  Mr.  Mawdsley  (Amalgamated  Association  of  Cotton-spinners)  is  very  emphatic 
on  this  point.  "  If  we  had  arbitration  we  should  have  much  less  wages  than  we 
are  getting  now.  Arbitrators  generally  go  in  for  a  certain  standard  of  profit  for 
capital — generally  speaking,  it  has  been  10  per  cent.  Mr.  Chamberlain  has 
always  said  that  capital  ought  to  have  10  per  cent.  If  the  arbitrator  went  in 
for  10  per  cent  in  the  cotton  trade,  we  should  have  a  very  big  reduction  of  wages; 
and  we  are  not  going  to  have  it." — Evidence  before  Royal  Commission  on 
Labor,  Group  C,  Answer  774.  We  believe  the  case  to  which  Mr.  Mawdsley 
referred  is  Mr.  Chamberlain's  award  in  the  South  Staffordshire  Iron  Trade  in 
1878. 


Arbitration  231 

influences  of  his  class  and  training.  The  persons  chosen 
as  arbitrators  have  almost  invariably  been  representative  of 
the  brain -working  class — great  employers,  statesmen,  or 
lawyers — men  bringing  to  the  task  the  highest  qualities  of 
training,  impartiality,  and  judgment,  but  unconsciously  imbued 
rather  with  the  assumptions  of  the  class  in  which  they  live 
than  with  those  of  the  workmen.  The  workmen's  growing 
objection  to  arbitration  is,  we  believe,  mainly  due  to  their 
deeply -rooted  suspicion  that  any  arbitrator  likely  to  be 
accepted  by  the  employers  will,  however  personally  impartial 
he  may  be,  unconsciously  discount  assumptions  inconsistent 
with  the  current  economics  of  his  class.1 

There  is,  however,  one  industry  in  which,  for  eight-and- 
twenty  years,  arbitration  has  been  habitually  resorted  to,  for 
the  settlement  of  the  terms  of  new  wage  contracts.  This 
one  exception  to  the  usual  dislike  of  arbitration  will,  we 
think,  prove  the  correctness  of  the  foregoing  analysis.  "  The 
Board  of  Conciliation  and  Arbitration  for  the  Manufactured 
Iron  Trade  of  the  North  of  England,"  which  has  existed  since 
1869,  has  long  been  the  classical  example  of  the  success 
of  arbitration.  Besides  providing  by  the  machinery  of  a 
standing  committee  for  the  settlement  of  interpretation 
differences,  and  by  half-yearly  board  meetings  for  discussing 
general  questions,  the  rules  direct  the  reference  of  intractable 
disputes  to  an  outside  umpire.  On  twenty  separate  occasions 

1  We  have  collected  particulars  of  no  fewer  than  240  cases  of  industrial 
arbitration,  ranging  from  1803  to  the  present  day.  Excluding  mere  questions 
of  interpretation,  and  disputes  between  workmen  themselves,  we  have  found  only 
one  case  in  which,  in  an  arbitration  for  a  new  agreement  between  employers  and 
employed,  any  person  of  the  wage-earning  class  has  been  accepted  as  umpire. 
In  May  1893  the  Northampton  Board  of  Arbitration  for  the  Boot  and  Shoe 
Trade  appointed  Mr.  F.  Perkins,  a  working  laster,  as  umpire.  (Monthly  Report 
of  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives,  May  1893). 

The  arduous  and  often  thankless  task  of  acting  as  umpire  or  sole  arbitrator  is 
usually  undertaken  without  fee  or  reward  of  any  kind.  Lord  James  has  long 
given  his  invaluable  services  to  the  boot  and  shoe  trade  without  remuneration. 
Dr.  Spence  Watson,  who  lately  completed  his  fiftieth  arbitration,  told  us  that  he 
had  only  thrice  received  any  payment  whatever,  once  his  railway  expenses,  once 
a  small  fee,  and  in  one  case,  which  involved  several  weeks'  labor,  a  more  substantial 
payment.  The  barrister-umpire,  called  in,  in  some  sense  as  a  professional  expert 
to  unravel  an  intricate  case,  is  occasionally  paid. 


232  Trade  Union  Function 

during  the  last  twenty-eight  years  this  provision  has  come 
into  operation  with  regard  to  the  settlement  of  the  con- 
ditions of  future  wage  contracts  ;  and  on  every  occasion  the 
arbitrator's  award  has  been  accepted  by  both  employers  and 
employed. 

It  is  an  interesting  confirmation  of  the  view  we  have 
taken  that,  in  this  one  industry  in  which  arbitration  has 
achieved  a  continued  success,  we  find  the  workmen  and  the 
employers  agreeing  in  the  economic  assumptions  upon  which 
wages  should  be  fixed,  and  upon  which,  therefore,  the  arbitrator 
is  asked  to  proceed.  It  has  for  more  than  a  generation  been 
traditional  among  ironmasters  that  the  wages  of  the  opera- 
tives ought  to  vary  with  the  market  price  of  the  product.1 
Since  the  formation  of  the  Board,  in  1869,  this  assumption 
has  been  accepted  by  both  parties  as  the  main,  and  often  as 
the  exclusive,  rule  for  the  settlement  of  wages.  In  the  reports 
of  the  arbitration  proceedings  we  find  both  parties  constantly 
reaffirming  this  principle,  each  in  turn  resorting  to  other 
considerations  only  for  the  sake  of  argument  when  the  main 
assumption  is  for  the  moment  calculated  to  tell  against  them. 
"  We  entirely  agree,"  declare  the  operatives  in  1877,"  that  our 
wages  should  be  regulated  by  the  selling  price  of  iron."2  Next 
time  it  is  the  employers  who  assert  the  same  rule.  "  The 
eight  years  sliding-scale  arrangement,"  states  their  spokesman 
in  1882,  "we  believe  was  the  principle  of  determining  wages 
by  the  selling  price  of  iron,  and  it  would  be  extremely  diffi- 
cult, if  not  dangerous,  permanently  to  depart  from  that."8 
There  is,  in  fact,  as  a  careful  student  observes,  "  a  general 
understanding  running  throughout  the  cases  and  pleadings, 
both  of  masters  and  men,  that  wages  should  follow  the 

1  See  the  illustration  quoted  at  pp.  484-486  of  the  History  of  Trade  Unionism. 
"Old  Thorneycroft's  Scale,"  by  which  puddlers'  wages  advanced  or  receded  one 
shilling  for  each  pound  sterling  per  ton  in  the  price  of  "marked  bars,"  dates,  it 
is  said,  from  1841  ;  see  Mr.  Whitwell's  evidence  before  Royal  Commission  on 
Labor,  1892,  Group  A. 

2  Report  of  Arbitration  before  Mr.  (now  Sir  David)  Dale,  July  1877,  Indus- 
trial Peace  >  p.  63. 

3  Report  of  Arbitration  before  Mr.  (now  Sir  J.  W.)  Pease,  April  1882,  Ibid. 
p.  63. 


Arbitration 


233 


selling  prices  of  iron."  l  This  was  expressly  stated  by  Dr.  R. 
Spence  Watson  in  the  letter  which  accompanied  his  fifth 
award  as  arbitrator  for  this  board.  Whilst  observing  that 
"  the  wages  paid  in  the  Staffordshire  district,  which  competes 
with  the  North  of  England  in  the  employment  of  ironworkers, 
as  well  as  to  some  extent  in  the  trade  itself,  is  a  factor  which 
cannot  be  disregarded,  [he  declares  that]  in  the  course  of  the 
arguments  it  was  admitted  on  both  sides  that  .  .  .  the  realised 
price  of  iron,  as  shown  by  the  figures  taken  out  by  the 
accountant  to  the  board,  may  be  considered  the  principal 
factor  in  the  regulation  of  wages.  ...  It  is  upon  this  state- 
ment [he  continues]  and  these  admissions  that  I  am  called 
upon  to  give  my  award."  2 

It   will   be   apparent   that   arbitration    on  issues   of  this 
kind  comes  really  within  the  category  of  the  interpretation 

>r  application  of  what  is,  in  effect,  an  agreement  already 
arrived  at  between  the  parties.  The  question  comes  very 
near  to  being  one  of  fact,  answered  as  soon  as  the  necessary 

igures  are  ascertained  beyond  dispute.  It  is  therefore  not 
surprising  to  learn  that,  during  eight  of  the  twenty-eight 

rears  of  the  Board's  existence,  variations  of  wages  were 
automatically  determined  by  a  formal  sliding  scale,  and  that 
even  during  the  intervals  in  which  no  definite  scale  was 
adopted  the  Board  itself  was  able,  on  eight  separate  occa- 
sions, to  agree  to  advances  or  reductions  without  troubling 
the  arbitrator  at  all.  We  need  not  discuss  whether  the 
acceptance  by  employers  and  operatives  alike  of  the 
assumption  that  wages  must  follow  prices  is,  or  is  not, 
advantageous  to  the  workmen,  or  to  the  industry  as  a 
whole.  But  it  is  evident  that  the  continued  success  of 

irbitration  in  the  North  of  England  Iron  Board,  dealing,  as 
it  does,  mainly  with  the  interpretation  or  application  of  an 
existing  common  basis  of  agreement,  affords  no  guide  to 
ler  trades  in  which  no  such  common  basis  is  accepted, 

1  Industrial  Peace,  p.  90. 

2  Letter  and  award  of  the  28th  November  1888  ;  Report  of  Wages  Arbitration 
before  R.  S.  Watson,  Esq.,  LL.D.  (Darlington,  1888). 


234  Trade  Union  Function 

and  in  which  the  claims  of  the  respective  parties  rest  on 
opposite  assumptions.1 

But  the  success  of  the  North  of  England  Manufactured 
Iron  Board,  and  the  more  qualified  results  of  similar 
tribunals  in  the  Midland  iron  trade,  and  the  Northumber- 
land and  Durham  coal-mining  industry,  whilst  they  give  no 
real  support  to  arbitration  as  a  panacea  for  strikes,  seem  at 
first  to  open  up  a  new  field  of  usefulness  for  the  arbitrator 
in  the  settlement  of  issues  of  application  or  interpretation. 
These  questions  of  interpretation  or  application  to  particular 
cases  are  always  arising,  even  in  the  best-regulated  trade, 
and  to  provide  machinery  for  their  peaceful  and  indisputable 
decision  is  of  great  importance.  Here  we  have  not  merely 
identical  assumptions  by  the  two  parties,  but  a  precise 
bargain  by  which  both  agree  to  be  bound.  Unfortunately 
it  is  just  in  these  issues,  for  which  arbitration  seems  a 
natural  expedient,  that  its  adoption  has  been  found,  in 
practice,  most  difficult.  The  application  of  a  general  agree- 
ment to  the  earnings  of  particular  individuals,  or  to  the 

1  The  Midland  Iron  and  Steel  Wages  Board,  which  has  had  an  intermittent 
existence  since  1872,  was  formed  on  the  model  of  the  North  of  England  Board, 
which  it  closely  resembles.  Owing  to  the  inferior  organisation  of  the  workmen 
in  Staffordshire  and  Worcestershire,  it  has  not  always  worked  smoothly,  but 
wage  variations  have  almost  always  been  made  by  the  Board  according  to  a 
sliding  scale,  formal  or  implied,  whilst  a  standing  committee  applies  the  general 
principles  to  "local  questions."  See  the  evidence  of  Mr.  (now  Sir  B.)  Hingley 
before  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor,  1892,  and  the  references  given  in  the 
preceding  chapter. 

Among  the  Northumberland  and  Durham  coalminers,  though  arbitration  as 
to  the  terms  of  new  agreements  has  been  repeatedly  resorted  to,  it  has  been  only 
partially  successful  in  preventing  strikes.  The  Northumberland  Miners'  Mutual 
Confident  Association  went  to  arbitration  on  five  occasions  between  1873  and 
1877.  But  in  1878  the  owners  forced  a  reduction  without  submitting  to  arbitra- 
tion, the  result  being  a  nine  weeks'  strike.  Between  1879  and  1886  the  level  of 
wages  was  automatically  regulated  by  a  sliding  scale.  In  1887  the  employers 
again  insisted  on  a  special  reduction,  the  result  being  a  disastrous  strike  of 
seventeen  weeks.  Since  that  date  alterations  in  the  level  of  wages  have  been 
mutually  agreed  to  by  the  joint  "  Wages  Committee  "  without  resort  to  arbitra- 
tion. The  Durham  Miners'  Association  (established  1869)  had  four  arbitrations 
between  1874  and  1876,  and  worked  under  a  sliding  scale  from  1877  to  1889. 
This  did  not  prevent  a  six  weeks'  strike  in  1879,  terminated  by  another  arbitra- 
tion. Variations  in  wages  between  1889  and  1892  were  mutally  agreed  to,  but 
in  1892  there  ensued  the  longest  and  most  embittered  dispute  ever  known  in  the 
trade. 


Arbitration  235 

technical  details  of  particular  samples  or  processes,  is  at 
once  too  complicated,  and  of  too  little  pecuniary  importance, 
to  make  it  possible  to  call  in  an  outside  arbitrator.1  The 
intractable  questions,  to  take  one  trade  as  an  example, 
which  perplex  the  local  boards  in  the  boot  and  shoe 
industry  relate  only  to  a  few  shillings,  and  frequently 
concern  only  one  or  two  workmen.  For  such  issues  it  is 
obviously  impossible  to  obtain,  either  for  love  or  money,  the 
services  of  any  personality  eminent  enough  to  command  the 
respect  of  the  whole  body  of  employers  and  workmen. 
Where  the  standard  of  earnings  of  large  bodies  of  men,  or 
the  prevention  of  a  serious  industrial  war,  are  concerned, 
public  spirit  will  induce  men  of  the  calibre  of  Lord  James 
or  Dr.  Spence  Watson  to  spend  whole  days,  without  fee  or 
reward,  in  bringing  about  an  adjustment.  In  commercial 
arbitrations  which  involve  considerable  sums,  recourse  is  had 
to  eminent  lawyers,  who  are  paid  large  fees  for  mastering 
the  intricate  details  of  each  case.  This  sort  of  arbitrator  is 
far  too  expensive  a  person  to  be  available  for  the  applica- 
tion of  general  wage  contracts  to  particular  cases,  and  the 
statesman  or  philanthropist  cannot  spare  the  time.  On  the 
other  hand,  if,  as  in  the  boot  and  shoe  trade,  recourse  is  had 
to  some  one  engaged  in  the  industry,  it  is  difficult  to  avoid 
the  suspicion  of  class  bias.  The  big  employer  from  another 
district,  whose  services  are  usually  called  in,  can  hardly  be 
expected  to  content  the  workmen.  The  employers,  on  the 

1  Thus,  when  in  1891,  in  an  arbitration  between  the  West  Cumberland  Iron 
and  Steel  Company  and  their  workmen,  the  arbitrator  (Dr.  Spence  Watson)  was 
asked  to  fix  the  actual  rates  at  which  particular  men  were  to  be  paid,  he  declined 
the  task  as  one  outside  the  possible  capacity  of  any  arbitrator.  "  What  has 
always  happened,"  said  Dr.  Spence  WTatson,  "in  every  arbitration  I  have  had 
hitherto  ?  There  has  been  a  general  question  of  percentage.  .  .  .  The  principle 
of  the  thing  is  the  thing  to  leave  to  arbitration.  The  detail  of  the  thing,  as  to 
how  it  is  to  affect  this  or  that  or  the  other,  never  can  be  left  to  arbitration.  .  .  . 
Already  over  this  matter  I  have  given  up  several  nights  to  go  through  these 
papers  and  work  them  in  this  way  and  that  way,  but  I  have  not  the  knowledge, 
and  you  cannot  give  me  the  knowledge.  .  .  .  Surely  the  question  of  individual 
payment  is  a  question  for  the  manager  of  the  works  and  the  men  of  the  works, 
and  not  for  a  third  party." — MS.  proceedings.  We  are  indebted  to  Dr.  Spence 
Watson  for  permission  to  examine  these  and  other  papers,  and  for  many  valuable 
suggestions  and  criticisms. 


236  Trade  Union  Function 

other  hand,  will  not  consent  to  be  bound  by  the  decision  of 
an  operative. 

It  is,  fortunately,  unnecessary  for  the  employers  and 
workmen  to  get  into  this  dilemma.  The  correct  analogy 
from  the  commercial  world  for  all  these  issues  of  interpreta- 
tion is,  not  the  elaborate  and  costly  reference  to  arbitration, 
but  the  simple  arrangements  for  taking  an  inventory,  in 
connection  with  a  contract  of  purchase  or  hire.  Instead  of 
calling  in  an  outside  authority,  eminent  enough  to  be  known 
and  trusted  by  both  sides,  each  party  is  represented  by  an 
inexpensive  expert  habitually  engaged  on  the  particular 
calculations  involved.  The  two  professional  men  seldom 
find  any  difficulty  in  agreeing  upon  an  identical  award. 
This  corresponds  exactly  to  the  machinery  which  is  em- 
ployed with  such  success  in  the  Lancashire  cotton  trade. 
The  two  secretaries  who  visit  the  mill  in  which  any  question 
of  interpretation  has  arisen  correspond  in  all  essentials  to 
the  two  house-agents  employed  respectively  by  the  owner 
and  the  incoming  tenant  of  a  furnished  house.  In  the 
interpretation  of  wage  contracts  there  is  even  more  justifi- 
cation for  this  method  than  in  taking  an  inventory.  The 
object  of  the  house-agent  on  either  side  is  to  get  the  best 
terms  for  his  client.  But  the  professional  experts  who  visit 
a  cotton  mill,  in  response  to  a  complaint  from  operative  or 
employer,  are  not  employed  by  or  responsible  to  either  of 
the  parties  directly  concerned.  And  though  one  represents 
the  associated  employers,  and  the  other  the  combined  work- 
men, both  are  retained  and  paid  to  secure  an  identical 
object,  namely,  absolute  uniformity  between  mill  and  mill. 
So  far  as  regards  the  application  to  the  particular  cases  of 
existing  general  contracts  between  employers  and  workmen, 
arbitration,  though  possible,  is  therefore  but  a  clumsy  device. 
The  only  way  of  getting  an  efficient  umpire  for  such 
technical  work  would  be  permanently  to  employ  a  pro- 
fessional expert  of  high  standing  to  give  his  whole  time  to 
the  business.  But  directly  an  industry  is  sufficiently  well 
organised  to  afford  the  expense  of  an  efficient  paid  umpire, 


Arbitration  237 

it  can  find  in  the  joint  meeting  of  the  salaried  experts  of 
both  sides  a  far  more  speedy,  economical,  and  uniform 
method  of  settling  questions  of  interpretation  than  any 
arbitration  could  provide.1 

The  reader  is  now  in  a  position  to  estimate  how  far 
arbitration  is  likely  to  serve  as  a  panacea  against  strikes  or 
lock-outs,  or  even  to  become  a  permanent  feature  of  the 
most  highly  organised  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining. 
In  the  really  crucial  instances — the  issues  relating  to  the 
conclusion  of  a  new  agreement — habitual  and  voluntary 
recourse  to  an  umpire  may  be  expected,  we  think,  only  in 
the  unlikely  event  of  capitalists  and  workmen  adopting 
identical  assumptions  as  to  the  proper  basis  of  wages.  We 
have  seen  how  unreservedly  the  best-educated  workmen  of 
the  North  of  England  accepted,  between  1870  and  1885, 
the  capitalists'  assumption  that  it  was  only  fair  that  wages 
should  vary  with  the  selling  price  of  the  product.  For 
twenty  years  the  miners  of  South  Wales  have  acquiesced  in 
the  same  doctrine.  If  this  view  were  to  become  accepted  in 
other  trades,  it  is  conceivable  that  arbitration  would  become 
more  popular  among  them.  On  the  other  hand,  there  is 
growing  up  among  workmen  a  strong  feeling  in  favor  of  a 
fixed  minimum  Standard  of  Life,  to  be  regarded  as  a  first 
charge  upon  the  industry  of  the  country,  and  to  be  deter- 
mined by  the  requirements  of  healthy  family  life  and 
citizenship.  If  the  capitalists  should  accept  this  view, 
arbitrations  might  become  common,  the  explicit  reference, 
in  every  case  being  what  conditions  were  required  in  the 
industry  to  enable  the  various  grades  of  producers  to  lead 
a  civilised  life.  But  no  such  agreement  on  fundamental 
assumptions  is  at  present  within  view.  We  are  therefore 

1  In  the  rare  cases  in  which  the  two  house-agents  fail  to  agree,  we  understand 
that  the  practice  is  for  them  privately  to  refer  the  matter  to  another  professional, 
whose  decision  they  both  adopt  as  their  own.  If  in  the  Lancashire  cotton  trade, 
the  employers'  and  workmen's  district  secretaries  do  not  agree  upon  an  issue  of 
interpretation,  it  is,  in  practice,  referred  to  the  joint  decision  of  the  central 
secretaries.  But  on  such  issues  of  fact,  if  identical  principles  are  thoroughly 
accepted  by  loth  sides,  there  is  seldom  any  intractable  difference  of  opinion  between 
frofessipnaj  experts. 


238  Trade  Union  Function 

constrained  not  to  place  any  high  expectations  upon  the 
fiat  of  an  umpire  as  a  method  of  preventing  disputes  as  to 
future  conditions  of  labor.  Nor  can  we  estimate  very 
highly  the  practical  value  of  arbitration  in  the  application 
to  particular  cases  of  existing  general  agreements.  In 
promptitude,  technical  efficiency,  and  inexpensiveness  the 
"  impartial  outsider "  is  inferior  to  the  joint  meeting  of  the 
salaried  secretaries  of  either  side. 

But  although  arbitration  is  not  likely  to  supersede 
Collective  Bargaining,  or  to  prevent  the  occasional  breaking 
off  of  negotiations,  it  has  great  advantages,  in  all  but  the 
best-organised  trades,  as  a  means  of  helping  forward  the 
negotiations  themselves.  The  first  requisite  for  efficient 
Collective  Bargaining  is  for  the  parties  to  meet  face  to  face, 
and  in  an  amicable  manner  to  discuss  each  other's  claim. 
But  this  initial  step  is  often  one  of  difficulty.  We  are  apt 
to  forget,  in  view  of  the  regular  negotiations  in  such  highly 
organised  trades  as  the  Cotton  Operatives,  the  Boilermakers, 
and  the  Northumberland  and  Durham  Coalminers,  how  new 
and  unusual  it  still  is  for  capitalists  and  workmen  to  meet 
on  an  equal  footing,  to  recognise  each  other's  representative 
capacity,  and  to  debate,  with  equal  good  temper,  technical 
knowledge,  and  argumentative  skill,  upon  what  conditions 
the  employer  shall  engage  "  his  own  hands."  Even  to-day, 
in  the  great  majority  of  trades,  the  masters  would  think  it 
beneath  their  dignity  voluntarily  to  confer  with  the  Trade 
Union  leaders  on  equal  terms  ;  and  they  would  resent  as 
preposterous  the  idea  of  disclosing  to  them  their  profit  and 
loss  accounts,  or  even  the  prices  they  are  obtaining  for  their 
product.  Yet  it  is  upon  these  facts  that  they  base  their 
demand  for  a  reduction  of  wages,  or  their  refusal  of  an 
advance.  The  workmen,  on  the  other  hand,  especially  in 
such  half-organised  trades,  are  full  of  prejudices,  misconcep- 
tions of  the  facts,  and  Utopian  aspirations.  Under  these 
circumstances,  even  if  the  employers  consent  to  meet  the 
men  at  all,  there  can  be  no  frank  interchange  of  views,  no 
real  understanding  of  each  other's  position — in  short,  no 


Arbitration  239 

effective  negotiation.  Recourse  to  an  impartial  umpire  is 
one  way  out  of  these  difficulties.  The  employer's  dignity  is 
not  offended  by  appearing  before  an  eminent  jurist  or  states- 
man, sitting  virtually  in  a  judicial  capacity.  It  is  regarded 
as  only  natural  that  the  arbitrator  should  ask  for  the 
statistical  facts  upon  which  each  party  bases  its  case.  The 
mere  fact  of  each  having  to  set  forth  its  claims  in  pre- 
cise terms,  in  a  way  that  can  be  maintained  under  cross- 
examination,  is  already  a  great  gain.  But  if  the  arbitrator 
is  tactful  and  experienced,  he  can  do  a  great  deal  more 
to  bring  the  parties  to  agreement.  He  discovers,  by  kindly 
examination,  what  precisely  it  is  that  each  party  regards  as 
essential,  and  persuasively  puts  on  one  side  any  irritating 
reminiscences  of  past  disputes,  or  theoretic  arguments  going 
beyond  the  narrow  limits  of  the  case.  In  friendly  conversa- 
tion with  each  side  in  turn,  he  draws  out  the  really  strong 
arguments  of  both,  restates  them  in  their  most  effective  form, 
and  in  due  course  impresses  them,  in  the  most  conciliatory 
terms,  on  the  notice  of  the  opponent.  Those  who  have  read 
the  proceedings  before  such  an  experienced  arbitrator  as  Dr. 
Spence  Watson,  will,  we  are  sure,  agree  with  us  in  feeling 
that  his  wonderful  success  as  an  umpire  is  far  more  due  to 
these  arts  of  conciliation  than  to  any  infallibility  in  his 
awards.  In  case  after  case  we  have  been  struck  by  the  fact 
that,  long  before  the  end  of  the  discussion,  many  of  the  issues 
had  already  been  disposed  of,  the  points  remaining  in  dis- 
pute being  so  narrowed  down  by  a  mutual  recognition  of 
each  other's  case  that  when  the  award  is  at  last  given  each 
party  is  predisposed  to  accept  it  as  inevitable. 

In  this  patient  work  of  conciliation  lies  the  real  value  of 
arbitration  proceedings.  There  is  no  magic  in  the  fiat  of  an 
arbitrator  as  a  remedy  for  strikes  or  lock-outs.  If  either 
party  really  prefers  fighting  to  conceding  the  smallest  point 
to  its  adversary — that  is,  in  those  cases  in  which  either  em- 
ployers or  the  workmen  have  an  overwhelming  superiority 
in  strength — there  will  be  no  submission  to  arbitration.  If 
both  parties  are  willing  to  bargain,  and  are  sufficiently  well 


240  Trade  Union  Function 

organised  and  well  educated  to  be  capable  of  it,  no  outside 
intervention  will  be  needed.  In  those  industries,  however, 
where  organisation  has  begun,  but  has  not  yet  reached  the 
highest  form  ;  where  the  employers  are  forced  to  recognise 
the  power  of  the  men's  union,  but  have  not  yet  brought 
themselves  to  meet  its  officials  on  terms  of  real  equality  ; 
where  the  workmen  are  strong  enough  to  strike,  but  do  not 
yet  command  the  services  of  experienced  negotiators,  the 
intervention  of  an  eminent  outsider  may  be  of  the  utmost 
value.  It  is  of  small  importance  whether  his  intervention 
takes  the  form  of  "  arbitration  "  or  "  conciliation  " — that  is 
to  say,  whether  he  is  empowered  to  close  the  discussion  by 
himself  delivering  an  "  award "  as  umpire,  or  whether  he 
must  wait  until  he  can  bring  the  parties  to  sign  an  "  agree- 
ment" drawn  up  by  himself  as  chairman.  In  either  case 
his  real  business  is  not  to  supersede  the  process  of  Collective 
Bargaining,  but  to  forward  it.  And  in  view  of  the  usual 
impossibility  of  agreeing  upon  any  common  assumption  as 
to  the  proper  basis  of  wages  ;  in  face  of  the  workman's 
suspicion  of  the  brainworker's  training,  and  the  employer's 
fear l  of  electioneering  considerations  ;  and  having  regard  to 
the  importance  of  securing  universal  concurrence  in  the 
result,  we  are  inclined  to  believe  that  the  intervention  of  the 
"  eminent  outsider "  will,  as  a  rule,  be  at  once  more  accept- 
able and  more  likely  to  be  successful  if  he  avowedly  acts 
only  as  a  "  conciliator."  2 

This  inference  is  supported  by  the  events  of  the  last  few 
years.  On  three  notable  occasions  outside  intervention  has 
been  evoked  to  settle  a  serious  industrial  conflict.  In  1893 
Lord  Rosebery,  at  the  express  desire  of  the  Cabinet,  settled 
a  dispute  which  had  for  sixteen  weeks  stopped  the  coal 

1  Thus,  in  the  draft  rules  of  a  Foreman's  Benefit  Society,  established  by  some 
of  the  leading  Tyneside  employers,  there  is  a  provision  for  referring  to  arbitration 
any  dispute    between   the  society  and  a  member.     The  draft  rule  significantly 
adds  :   "  The  following  cannot  be  selected  as  arbitrator  :  Persons  either  candi- 
dates for  or  holding  political,  municipal,  or  other  positions  acquired  by  votes ; 
ministers  of  religion." 

2  "In  conciliation  the  disputants  endeavour  to  convince  each  other,  in  arbi« 
tration  to  convince  a  third  party.     As  in.  the  first  case,  both  sides  have  equa? 


A  rbitration  2  4 1 

trade  of  the  Midlands  of  England.  In  1895  Sir  Courtenay 
Boyle,  Permanent  Secretary  of  the  Board  of  Trade,  drew 
up  the  agreement  which  terminated  the  great  strike  in  the 
boot  trade.  And  Lord  James,  a  distinguished  member  of 
the  Conservative  Ministry  of  the  day,  in  January  1896 
brought  about,  after  protracted  negotiations,  a  settlement 
of  the  dispute  between  the  Clyde  and  Belfast  shipbuilders 
and  their  engineers.  But  notwithstanding  the  official  posi- 
tion of  these  magnates,  it  is  significant  that  in  no  case  were 
they  asked,  and  in  no  case  did  they  attempt,  to  cut  the 
Gordian  knot  by  the  judicial  decree  of  an  umpire  or  arbi- 
trator. It  was  not  their  business  to  inquire  into  the  merits 
of  the  case.  They  were  not  called  upon  to  make  up  their 
minds  whether  the  employers  or  the  workmen  were  in  the 
right.  They  had  not  even  to  choose  between  the  rival 
economic  assumptions  on  which  the  parties  rested  their 
respective  claims.  Their  function  was  to  persuade  the 
representatives  of  both  sides  to  go  on  negotiating  until  a 
basis  was  discovered  on  which  it  was  possible  for  them  to 
agree. 

This  work  of  conciliation  is,  we  believe,  destined  to  play 
a  great  and  for  many  years  an  increasing  part  in  the  labor 
struggles  of  this  country.  In  the  present  state  of  public 
opinion  the  intervention  of  an  outside  "  conciliator "  is,  as 
regards  the  imperfectly  organised  trades,  a  precursor  of 
regular  Collective  Bargaining.  In  many  trades  the  em- 
ployers themselves  are  not  united  in  any  association  :  in 
many  others  they  still  haughtily  refuse  to  discuss  matters 
with  their  workmen.  In  prolonged  disputes  public  opinion 
now  almost  forces  the  parties  to  resume  negotiations ;  and 

knowledge  of  the  matter  in  hand,  they  must  endeavour  to  show  clearly  the  strong 
points  of  the  case,  and  those  only.  Any  attempt  at  simple  advocacy  would  be 
thrown  away.  The  appeal  must  be  to  acknowledged  facts.  But,  in  the  second 
case,  advocacy  is  necessary,  and  all  its  many  devices — the  undesirable  as  well  as 
the  undeniably  good.  There  is  a  strong  antagonism  throughout.  Arbitration  is 
better  than  striking  or  locking  out,  but  inferior  to  conciliation.  Industrial  peace 
in  any  form  is  better  than  industrial  war." — "  Compulsory  or  Voluntary  Concilia- 
tion," by  R.  Spence  Watson,  Ironworkers'  Journal,  June  1895. 

VOL.  I  R 


242  Trade  Union  Function 

the  intervention  of  an  eminent  outsider  is  found  the  best 
lever  for  Collective  Bargaining.  His  social  position  or  official 
status  secures  for  the  proceedings,  even  among  angry  men, 
a  certain  amount  of  dignity,  order,  and  consideration  for 
each  other's  feelings,  whilst  it  prevents  any  hasty  rupture 
or  withdrawal.  So  long  as  Lord  Rosebery  was  willing  to 
go  on  sitting,  it  was  practically  impossible  for  either  the 
coalowners  or  the  coalminers  to  stop  discussing.  But  pro- 
longed discussion  does  not  lead  to  agreement  unless  the 
parties  get  on  good  terms  with  each  other,  and  are  brought 
into  a  friendly  mood.  It  is  the  conciliator's  business  to  see 
that  this  atmosphere  of  good  humour  is  produced  and  main- 
tained. The  excellent  luncheon  which  Lord  Rosebery  pro- 
vided for  owners  and  workmen  alike  was  probably  more 
effective  in  creating  harmony  than  the  most  convincing 
arguments  about  "the  living  wage."  All  this,  however,  is 
but  preliminary  to  the  real  business.  We  have  already 
described  the  important  part  played  by  a  tactful  and  ex- 
perienced arbitrator  in  drawing  out  the  best  points  in  each 
party's  case,  restating  them  in  the  most  persuasive  form,  and 
eliminating  from  the  controversy  all  unnecessary  sources  of 
irritation  or  non-essential  differences.  The  ideal  conciliator 
adds  to  this  a  happy  suggestiveness  and  fertility  in  devising 
possible  alternatives.  Throughout  the  discussion  he  watches 
for  the  particular  points  to  which  each  party  really  attaches 
importance.  He  has  a  quick  eye  for  acceptable  lines  of 
compromise.  At  the  right  psychological  moment,  when 
discussion  is  beginning  to  be  tedious  to  both  sides,  he  is 
ready  with  a  form  of  words.  This  is  the  crisis  of  the  pro- 
ceedings. If  the  parties  are  physically  and  mentally  tired, 
and  yet  pleased  with  themselves  and  no  longer  angry  with 
their  opponents  ;  if  the  conciliator  is  adroit  in  his  drafting, 
and  finds  a  formula  which,  whilst  making  mutual  concessions 
on  minor  points,  includes,  or  seems  to  each  party  to  include, 
a  great  deal  of  what  each  has  been  contending  for,  the 
resolution  will  be  agreed  to,  if  not  by  acclamation,  at 
any  rate  after  a  few  minor  amendments  to  save  the  dignity 


Arbitration 


243 


of  one  side  or  the  other ;  and  almost  before  some  of  the 
slower-minded  representatives  have  had  time  to  think  out  all 
the  bearings  of  the  compromise  the  agreement  is  signed,  and 
peace  is  secured. 

We  see,  therefore,  that  outside  intervention  in  wages 
disputes  may  be  of  the  highest  value,  and  we  anticipate  that 
it  will,  for  many  years  to  come,  in  all  but  the  best-organised 
trades,  play  a  great,  and  even  an  increasing,  part.  But  its 
function  will  not  be  that  of  "  arbitration,"  properly  so  called, 
but  rather  that  of  "conciliation,"  though  this  will  continue 
to  be  sometimes  carried  on  under  the  guise  of  arbitration. 
Instead  of  aiming  at  superseding  Collective  Bargaining,  the 
arbitrator  will  more  and  more  consciously  seek  to  promote 
it.  In  fact,  so  far  from  being  the  crown  of  industrial  organ- 
isation, the  reference  of  disputes  to  an  impartial  outsider  is 
a  mark  of  its  imperfection.  Arbitration  is  the  temporary 
expedient  of  incompletely  organised  industries,  destined  to 
be  cast  aside  by  each  of  them  in  turn  when  a  higher  stage, 
like  that  of  the  Cotton  Operatives  or  the  Boilermakers,  is 
attained.  The  Government  of  1896,  therefore,  did  well  to 
cut  down  its  arbitration  bill  to  a  modest  "  Conciliation  Act." 
The  pretentious  legislation  of  1867  and  1872,  from  which 
so  much  was  expected,  is  now  simply  repealed.  The  Board 
of  Trade  is  empowered,  in  case  of  an  industrial  dispute,  "  to 
inquire  into  the  causes  and  circumstances  of  the  difference." 
It  may  intervene  as  the  friend  of  peace,  to  persuade  the 
parties  to  come  to  an  agreement.  If  a  conciliator  is  desired, 
it  may  appoint  one.  Finally,  if  both  parties  join  in  asking 
that  the  settlement  shall  proceed  in  the  guise  of  arbitration, 
and  wish  the  Board  of  Trade  to  select  the  arbitrator  for  them, 
the  Board  of  Trade  may  accede  to  their  request,  as  it  might 
have  done  without  any  Act  at  all ! l 

1  The  report  of  the  first  year's  working  of  this  Act,  presented  to  Parliament 
in  July  1897,  shows  that  35  applications  were  made  to  the  Board  of  Trade.  In 
7  cases  the  Board  refused  to  intervene.  Of  the  other  28  cases,  18  were  settled 
by  more  or  less  formal  conciliation,  and  5  by  arbitration,  one  of  which  was  a 
demarcation  dispute  between  different  bodies  of  workmen,  and  the  other  4  were 
small  local  disputes,  all  in  badly-organised  trades  or  districts.  Three  cases, 


244  Trade  Union  Function 

The  conclusion  will  disappoint  those  who  see  in  arbitra- 
tion, not  a  subordinate  and  temporary  adjunct  to  Collective 
Bargaining,  but  a  panacea  for  stoppages  of  industry.  The 
popularity  of  arbitration  has  deep  roots.  At  the  back  of 
the  peremptory  public  demand  for  the  settlement  of  any 
strike  or  lock-out,  there  lurks  a  feeling  that  in  the  interests 
of  the  whole  community  neither  employers  nor  workmen 
ought  to  be  allowed  to  paralyse  their  own  industry.  If  one 
side  or  the  other  persists  in  standing  out,  we  have  a  clamour 
for  "  compulsory  arbitration " :  that  is,  the  intervention  of 
the  power  of  the  State.  We  need  not  enter  into  the  numer- 
ous suggestions  that  have  been  made  for  "  State  Boards  of 
Arbitration,"  authoritative  intervention  by  the  Board  of 
Trade,  or  the  deposit,  by  both  parties,  of  sums  of  money 
to  be  legally  forfeited  upon  breach  of  the  award.  The 
authors  of  such  suggestions  always  find  themselves  in  a 
dilemma.  If  resort  to  this  kind  of  arbitration  is  still  to 
be  voluntary,  the  liability  to  penalties  or  legal  proceedings 
is  not  calculated  to  persuade  either  employers  or  workmen 
to  come  within  its  toils.1  If,  on  the  other  hand,  it  is  to  be 
compulsory,  it  will  amount  to  legal  enactment  of  a  novel 
kind.  It  may  well  be  argued  that  the  community,  for  the 
protection  of  the  public  welfare,  is  entitled  to  step  in  and 

including  the  notorious  strike  at  Lord  Penrhyn's  slate  quarries,  and  that  of  the 
boot  operatives  at  Norwich,  remained  intractable,  owing  to  arbitration  being 
refused,  twice  by  the  employers  and  once  by  both  parties. 

1  The  following  extract  from  a  recent  report  of  so  experienced  and  well- 
informed  a  society  as  the  United  Textile  Factory  Workers'  Association  is 
significant :  "  Boards  of  Conciliation. — Any  number  of  Bills  are  constantly  being 
introduced  on  this  question,  but  your  Council  do  not  see  that  any  useful  purpose 
can  be  served  by  their  becoming  law.  The  assumption  on  which  all  these 
proposals  are  based  is  that  .  .  .  when  the  return  goes  down  the  wages  of  labor 
and  the  profits  of  capital  should  go  down  together.  .  .  .  The  umpire  is  never  a 
workman,  but  always  a  member  of  the  upper  class,  whose  sympathies  and  interest 
lie  in  the  direction  of  keeping  wages  down.  .  .  .  They  believe  that  the  Bills 
now  being  brought  forward  are  meant  as  so  many  traps  with  which  to  catch  a 
portion  of  the  workers'  wages,  and  they  have  consequently  opposed  them " 
(Report  of  the  Legislative  Council  of  the  United  Textile  Factory  Worker?  Associa- 
tion for  1893-94,  p.  14).  See  also  the  reports  of  the  conferences  between  the 
Miners'  Federation  and  the  leading  coalowners  during  1896,  in  which  the  work- 
men's representatives  throughout  opposed  any  arbitration  scheme  by  which,  as  they 
repeated,  "  a  man  can  come  in  and  settle  what  we  could  not  settle  among  ourselves. " 


Arbitration  245 

decide  the  terms  upon  which  mechanics  shall  labor,  and 
upon  which  capitalists  shall  engage  them.  In  such  a  case 
the  public  decision  could  perhaps  best  be  embodied  in  the 
award  of  an  impartial  arbitration  tribunal,  invested  with  all 
the  solemnity  of  the  State.  But  here  we  pass  outside  the 
domain  of  "  arbitration  "  properly  so  called.  The  question 
is  then  no  longer  the  patching  up  of  a  quarrel  between 
capitalists  and  workmen,  but  the  deliberate  determination 
by  the  community  of  the  conditions  under  which  certain 
industrial  operations  shall  be  allowed  to  be  carried  on. 
Such  an  award  would  have  to  be  enforced  on  the  parties 
whose  recalcitrance  had  rendered  it  necessary.  This  does 
not  imply,  as  is  sometimes  suggested,  that  workmen  would 
be  marched  into  the  works  by  a  regiment  of  soldiers,  or  that 
the  police  would  open  the  gates  (and  the  cashbox)  of  stubborn 
employers.  All  that  the  award  need  decree  is,  that  if 
capitalists  desire  to  engage  in  the  particular  industry  they 
shall  do  so  only  on  the  specified  conditions.  The  enforce- 
ment of  these  conditions  would  become  a  matter  for  official 
inspection,  followed  by  prosecutions  for  breaches  of  what 
would  in  effect  be  the  law  of  the  land.  Here,  it  is  true, 
we  do  find  an  effective  panacea  for  strikes  and  lock-outs. 
Although  industrial  history  records  plenty  of  agitations  and 
counter-agitations  for  and  against  the  fixing  by  law  of  various 
conditions  of  employment,  there  has  never  been  either  a 
lock-out  or  a  strike  against  a  new  Factory  or  Truck  Act. 
But  by  adopting  this  method  of  avoiding  the  occasional 
breaking  off  of  negotiations  which  accompanies  Collective 
Bargaining,  we  should  supersede  Collective  Bargaining  alto- 
gether. The  conditions  of  employment  would  no  longer 
be  left  to  the  higgling  of  masters  and  men,  but  would  be 
authoritatively  decided  without  their  consent  in  the  manner 
which  the  community,  acting  through  an  arbitrator,  thought 
most  expedient.  "  Compulsory  arbitration  "  means,  in  fact, 
the  fixing  of  wages  by  law.1 

1  Such  a  form  of  compulsory  arbitration  is  contained  in  the  Factories  and 
Shops  Act  of  1896  of  the  Colony  of  Victoria,  which  provides  (sec.  15)  that,   "in 


246  Trade  Union  Function 

order  to  determine  the  lowest  price  or  rate  which  may  be  paid  to  any  person  for 
wholly  or  partially  preparing  or  manufacturing  either  inside  or  outside  a  factory, 
or  workroom,  any  particular  articles  of  clothing,  or  wearing  apparel,  or  furniture, 
or  for  breadmaking,  or  baking,  the  Governor  in  Council  may,  if  he  think  fit, 
from  time  to  time  appoint  a  special  Board,"  to  consist  half  of  representatives  of 
employers  and  half  of  employed.  The  Board  may  then  prescribe  the  minimum 
rates  to  be  paid  for  particular  articles,  by  piecework  for  home  work,  and  by  either 
time  or  piece  for  factory  work.  Any  employer  paying  less  than  the  minimum 
thus  fixed  is  made  liable  to  a  fine,  and,  on  a  third  offence,  the  registration  of  his 
factory  or  workroom  (without  which  he  cannot  carry  on  business)  "shall,  without 
further  or  other  authority  than  this  Act,  be  forthwith  cancelled  by  the  Chief 
Officer."  The  working  of  this  virtually  legal  fixing  of  a  minimum  wage  will  be 
watched  with  interest  by  economists.  Under  the  New  Zealand  Act  of  1894, 
passed  by  the  Hon.  W.  P.  Reeves,  now  Agent-General  for  the  Colony  in  London, 
labor  disputes  in  which  Trade  Unions  are  concerned  may  be  referred,  first  to 
Public  Conciliation  Boards,  and,  failing  a  settlement,  to  an  Arbitration  Court, 
composed  of  a  Judge  of  the  Supreme  Court,  with  two  assessors.  This  Court 
may,  at  its  discretion,  make  its  award  enforceable  by  legal  process.  A  fuller 
account  of  this  Act  will  be  found  in  our  final  chapter.  The  Conciliation  and 
Arbitration  Acts  of  New  South  Wales  (1892)  and  South  Australia  (1894)  have 
been  practically  unsuccessful.  ("Quelques  experiences  de  la  Conciliation  par 
l'£tat  en  Australasie,"  by  Anton  Bertram  in  Revue  &£conomie 
July  1897.) 


CHAPTER    IV 

THE    METHOD    OF    LEGAL    ENACTMENT 

WE  do  not  need  to  remind  the  student  of  the  History  of 
Trade  Unionism  that  an  Act  of  Parliament  has,  at  all  times, 
formed  one  of  the  means  by  which  British  Trade  Unionists 
have  sought  to  attain  their  ends.  The  fervor  with  which 
they  have  believed  in  this  particular  Method,  and  the  extent 
to  which  they  have  been  able  to  employ  it  have  varied 
according  to  the  political  circumstances  of  the  time.  The 
strong  trade  clubs  of  the  town  handicraftsmen,  and  the 
widely  extended  associations  of  woollen  workers  of  the 
eighteenth  century  relied  mainly  upon  the  law  to  secure  the 
regulation  of  their  trades.  So  much  was  this  the  case  that 
the  most  celebrated  student  of  eighteenth -century  Trade 
Unionism  declares  that  "  the  legal  prosecution "  of  trans- 
gressors of  the  law  was  the  chief  object l  of  these  combina- 
tions, and  that,  in  fact,  English  Trade  Unionism  "originated 
with  the  non-observance  of"  the  statutes  fixing  wages  and 
regulating  apprenticeship.  Its  fundamental  purpose,  says  Pro- 
fessor Brentano,  was  "  the  maintenance  of  the  existing  legal 
and  customary  regulations  of  trade.  As  soon  as  the  State 
ceased  to  maintain  order  it  stepped  into  its  place."  2  It  is 
true  that  later  investigation  has  brought  to  light  some  ancient 
unions,  which,  springing  out  of  sick  clubs,  or  impetuous 

1  Brentano's  Gilds  and  Trade  Unions  (London,  1870),  p.  clxxiv.  (or  p.  no 
of  reprint). 

2  Ibid.  p.  clxxvii.  (or  p.  1 1 3  of  reprint). 


248  Trade  Union  Function 

strikes,  adhered  to  the  rival  Methods  of  Mutual  Insurance 
and  Collective  Bargaining.  But  Dr.  Brentano's  generalisa- 
tion as  to  the  objects  and  methods  of  eighteenth-century  com- 
binations has,  in  the  main,  been  confirmed  and  strengthened. 
It  would  have  been  remarkable  if  the  Trade  Unions  had  not 
taken  this  line.  Even  before  the  stringent  act  of  1799 
against  all  workmen's  combinations,  the  very  idea  of  Col- 
lective Bargaining  was  scouted  by  employers,  and  strongly 
condemned  by  public  opinion.  On  the  other  hand,  the 
majority  of  the  educated  and  the  governing  classes  regarded 
it  as  only  reasonable  that  the  conditions  of  labor  should  be 
regulated  by  law.  Accordingly  we  find  the  operatives  who 
objected  to  the  innovations  threatening  their  accustomed 
livelihood,  confidently  appealing  against  their  new  employers, 
to  Quarter  Sessions,  Parliament,  or  the  Privy  Council.  We 
see  the  Trade  Unions  forming  committees  to  put  the  law  in 
force  ;  maintaining  solicitors  to  fight  their  cases  in  the  law 
courts  ;  expending  large  sums  in  preparing  tables  of  rates, 
to  be  enforced  by  the  magistrates ;  marshalling  evidence 
before  Quarter  Sessions  in  support  of  these  lists  ;  appearing 
by  counsel  at  the  bar  of  the  House  of  Commons  and  before 
the  House  of  Lords  Committees  in  quest  of  new  legislation, 
or  in  opposition  to  bills  of  the  employers  ;  and  finally  organ- 
ising all  the  machinery  of  political  agitation,  with  its  showers 
of  petitions,  imposing  demonstrations  in  the  streets,  Parlia- 
mentary lobbying,  and  occasionally,  where  the  members 
happened,  as  freemen,  to  possess  the  franchise,  the  swaying 
of  elections.1 

With  the  adoption,  by  Parliament  and  the  law  courts, 
of  the  doctrine  of  laisser  faire,  all  this  machinery  fell  into 
abeyance.  It  soon  came  to  be  waste  of  money  to  organise 
petitions,  to  send  up  delegates  and  witnesses,  or  to  pay  the 
fees  of  solicitors  and  counsel,  only  to  be  met  by  a  doctrinaire 
refusal  to  go  into  the  merits  of  the  case.  From  1800 
onward  we  find  every  Committee  of  the  House  of  Commons 

1  Illustrations  of  all  these  forms  of  Trade  Union  activity  during  the  eighteenth 
century  will  be  found  in  the  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  27,  33,  34,  40-54. 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  249 

reporting  in  the  same  strain.  "  They  are  of  opinion  that  no 
interference  of  the  legislature  with  the  freedom  of  trade,  or 
with  the  perfect  liberty  of  every  individual  to  dispose  of  his 
time  and  of  his  labor  in  the  way  and  on  the  terms  which 
he  may  judge  most  conducive  to  his  own  interest  can  take 
place  without  violating  general  principles  of  the  first  import- 
ance to  the  prosperity  and  happiness  of  the  community, 
without  establishing  the  most  pernicious  precedent,  or  even 
without  aggravating,  after  a  very  short  time,  the  pressure  of 
the  general  distress,  and  imposing  obstacles  against  that 
distress  being  ever  removed." *  Debarred  alike  from  overt 
Collective  Bargaining  and  from  Legal  Enactment,  the  Trade 
Unions  of  the  first  quarter  of  the  century  fell  back  on  the 
Method  of  Mutual  Insurance,  largely  tempered  by  the  use 
of  secret  coercion.  Those  who  refused  to  work  "  contrary 
to  the  interests  of  the  trade  "  were  supported  with  enthusi- 
astic generosity,  whilst  "  knobsticks "  were  boycotted,  and 
even  assaulted.  When  employers  retaliated  by  criminal 
prosecution,  or  dismissal  of  Trade  Unionists,  the  operatives 
broke  out  into  sullen  strikes  or  angry  riots,  accompanied  by 
machine  breaking  and  crimes  of  violence.  It  was  largely 
the  hope  of  putting  an  end  to  this  veiled  insurrection  that 
induced  a  landlord  Parliament  to  repeal  the  Combination 
Laws,  and  thus,  for  the  first  time,  enabled  the  Trade  Unions 
openly  to  carry  on  negotiations  with  their  employers. 

Throughout  the  next  quarter  of  a  century  Trade  Union 
activity  was  mainly  devoted  to  building  up  the  machinery 
for  Collective  Bargaining.2  This  is  easily  explained.  Whilst 
the  Philosophic  Radicals,  and  indeed  much  of  the  educated 

1  Report  of  Committee  on  Petitions  of  Artisans,  I3th  June  1811  ;  History  of 
Trade  Unionism,  p.  54. 

2  The  fact  that  it  was  at  this  stage  in  their  history  that  the  working  class 
combinations  forced  themselves  on  the  attention  of  Political  Economists  and  the 
press,  goes  far,  we  think,  to  account  for  the  common  idea  that  Trade  Unionism 
consists  exclusively  of  Collective  Bargaining,  with  its  accompaniments  of  "  sticks 
and  strikes."      Between    1824   and    1869,    practically  all   the   criticism  or  de- 
nunciation of  Trade  Unionism  took  the  form  of  homilies  about  the  futility  of 
Collective  Bargaining  and  the  wickedness  of  strikes.     Even  the  Political  Econo- 
mists seem  to  have  been  unaware  either  of  the  history  of  the  combinations  which 


250  Trade  Union  Fimction 

public  opinion  of  that  generation,  worked  with  the  unions  in 
widening  and  safeguarding  their  resort  to  the  Method  of 
Collective  Bargaining,  any  idea  of  regulating  by  law  the 
conditions  of  labor  of  the  ordinary  workman  was  regarded 
by  a  middle-class  electorate  as  out  of  the  question.  Those 
industries  in  which  there  was  (owing  to  the  attention  of 
philanthropists  or  the  existence  of  peculiar  grievances)  any 
chance  of  obtaining  special  legislation  still  strove  to  enforce 
their  Common  Rules  by  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment. 
The  reader  of  the  History  of  Trade  Unionism  will  re- 
member how  vigorously  and  effectively  the  unions  of  textile 
workers  supported,  between  1830  and  1850,  the  various 
"  Ten  Hours'  "  bills  advocated  by  Robert  Owen  and  Lord 
Shaftesbury.  The  combinations  of  the  coalminers,  basing 
their  claims  on  the  unknown  horrors  of  underground  life, 
were  even  more  insistent,  from  1843  onward,  in  demand- 
ing successive  Mines  Regulation  Acts.  The  Hand-loom 
Weavers  and  the  Stocking -frame  Workers  long  continued 
pathetically  to  urge  the  old  arguments  in  favor  of  a 
legal  rate  of  wages,  whilst  all  sections  of  organised  workmen 
spasmodically  attempted  to  get  legal  protection  for  their 
earnings  by  an  effective  prohibition  of  "  truck."  But  with  a 
House  of  Commons  dominated  by  employers  of  labor,  the 
operatives  in  trades  employing  only  adult  males,  and  free 
from  exceptional  grievances,  for  the  most  part  laid  aside 
their  traditional  method. 

With  the  enfranchisement  of  the  town  artisan  in  1867, 
and  the  county  operative  and  miner  in  1885,  we  see  the 
relative  preference  between  the  three  methods  again  shifting. 
The  case  for  the  legal  limitation  of  the  hours  of  work  of 
adult  men  was,  for  instance,  explicitly  stated  at  the  beginning 
of  the  Cotton-spinners'  agitation  for  the  Nine  Hours'  Bill. 
"  We  are  often  told,"  declared  their  official  manifesto  in  1871, 
"  that  any  legislative  interference  with  male  adult  labor  is 

they  were  criticising,  or  of  the  nature  and  variety  of  their  objects  and  methods. 
This  lop-sided  appreciation  of  Trade  Union  purposes  and  Trade  Union  methods 
still  lingers  in  leading  articles  and  popular  economic  text-books. 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  25 1 

an  economic  error,  and  it  is  further  urged  that  as  the  labor 
of  the  working  man  is  his  only  capital,  he  should  not  be 
restrained  in  the  use  or  application  of  it.  ...  Now,  though 
at  first  sight  the  above  reasoning,  if  reasoning  it  may  be 
called — seems  plausible  enough,  yet  there  is  a  lurking  fallacy 
in  it  all  the  more  dangerous  because  of  the  artful  manner  in 
which  it  is  attempted  to  place  the  Legislature  and  the  work- 
ing population  in  a  false  position  in  relation  to  each  other. 
...  It  is  a  sound  principle  of  universal  law  established  by 
the  wisdom  of  more  than  two  thousand  years  that  where  in 
the  necessary  imperfection  of  human  affairs  the  parties  to  a 
contract  or  dealing  do  not  stand  on  an  equal  footing,  but  one 
has  an  undue  power  to  oppress  or  mislead  the  other,  law 
should  step  in  to  succour  the  weaker  party.  ...  It  behoves 
us  as  working  men  to  inquire  what  is  wrong  in  the  present 
factory  system,  and,  if  need  be,  ask  the  legislature  to  interfere 
in  our  behalf  .  .  .  whether  the  time  has  not  arrived  when 
Parliament  should  be  appealed  to  to  secure  a  curtailment  of 
the  hours  of  factory  labor.  ...  If  some  of  our  legislators 
should  manifest  a  disposition  to  abdicate  their  legislative 
functions  so  far  as  we  are  concerned,  it  may  be  well  to 
remind  them  that  election  day  will  again  come  round  when 
their  abdication  will  be  accepted."  * 

This  change  of  political  conditions  explains,  not  only  the 
increasing  demand  for  new  Factory  and  Mines  Acts,  addi- 
tional Railway  and  Merchant  Shipping  regulations,  and  the 
prevention  of  accidents  and  truck,  but  also  the  upgrowth, 
since  1868,  of  such  exclusively  political  Trade  Union  organi- 
sations as  the  United  Textile  Factory  Workers'  Association, 
and  such  predominantly  political  associations  as  the  Miners' 
Federation  of  Great  Britain,  together  with  the  formation  of 
a  general  political  machinery  throughout  the  Trade  Union 

1  Circular  signed  by  the  general  secretary  of  the  Amalgamated  Association  of 
Operative  Cotton-spinners,  "  on  behalf  of  "  the  delegate  meeting,  nth  December 
1871;  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  295-96.  It  will  be  remembered  that 
this  Trade  Union  has  always  consisted  exclusively  of  men.  In  our  History  of 
Trade  Unionism  we  have  pointed  out  how  the  Nine  Hours'  agitation  was  event- 
ually conducted  to  a  successful  issue  "  behind  the  women's  petticoats." 


252  Trade  Union  Function 

world,  in   the   form   of  Trades  Councils,  the   Trade  Union 
Congress,  and  the  Parliamentary  Committee. 

It  is  probable  that  no  one  who  is  not  familiar  with  Trade 
Union  records  has  any  adequate  conception  of  the  number 
and  variety  of  trade  regulations  which  the  unions  have 
sought  to  enforce  by  Act  of  Parliament.  The  eighteenth- 
century  combinations  seem  to  have  limited  their  aspirations 
to  the  fixing  of  a  minimum  rate  of  wages,  the  requirement 
of  a  period  of  apprenticeship,  and  the  determination  of  the 
proper  proportion  of  apprentices  to  journeymen.  With  the 
advent  of  manufacture  on  a  large  scale  we  see  the  factory 
operatives  and  miners  taking  up  the  subjects  of  sanitation 
and  overcrowding,  safety  from  accidents,  and  the  length  of 
the  working  day.  Besides  the  universal  demand  that  em- 
ployers should  be  made  liable  for  accidents,  and  forbidden  to 
make  any  deductions  from  wages,  we  have  large  sections  of 
the  Trade  Union  world  demanding  an  Eight  Hours'  Day,  the 
prohibition  of  overtime,  and  the  specifying  of  definite  holi- 
days ;  others  insisting  on  the  weekly  payment  of  wages,  the 
disclosure  of  the  "  particulars  "  on  which  the  piecework  wage 
is  based,  and  the  abolition  of  all  fines  and  deductions  what- 
soever. The  National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives 
ask  for  the  exclusion  of  alien  immigrants,  and  the  compulsory 
provision  of  workshop  accommodation  by  the  employers  ; 
whilst  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Tailors  will  be  content 
with  nothing  short  of  the  legal  abolition  of  home  work.  The 
Carmen  seek,  year  after  year,  for  an  Act  of  Parliament  to 
enforce  their  rule  that  one  man  shall  not  be  put  in  charge  of 
two  carts ;  the  Boilermakers,  Enginemen,  and  Plumbers  ask 
that  none  but  certificated  craftsmen  shall  be  allowed  to  hold 
certain  positions  ;  the  Textile  Workers  want  to  regulate  the 
temperature  and  humidity  of  the  spinning-mills  and  weaving 
sheds  ;  whilst  the  Seamen  have  a  lengthy  code  of  their  own 
extending  from  an  amendment  of  the  laws  of  marine  in- 
surance to  the  qualifications  of  a  sea-cook,  from  an  improved 
construction  of  sea-going  vessels  to  increasing  the  sum  allowed 
on  advance  notes,  from  the  enactment  of  a  fixed  scale  of 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  253 

manning  to  the  inspection  of  the  ship's  medicine  chest.  Nor 
does  this  enumeration  by  any  means  exhaust  the  list.  Every 
Parliament  sees  new  regulations  of  the  conditions  of  employ- 
ment embodied  in  the  already  extensive  labor  code,  whilst 
each  successive  Trade  Union  Congress  produces  a  crop  of 
fresh  demands.1  Whether  for  good  or  for  evil,  it  appears 
inevitable  that  the  growing  participation  of  the  wage-earners 
in  political  life,  and  the  rising  influence  of  their  organisations, 
must  necessarily  bring  about  an  increasing  use  of  the  Method 
of  Legal  Enactment. 

But  a  resort  to  the  law  as  a  means  of  attaining  Trade 
Union  ends  has,  from  the  workmen's  point  of  view,  certain 
grave  disadvantages.  Its  chief  drawback  is  the  prolonged 
and  uncertain  struggle  that  each  new  regulation  involves. 
Before  a  Trade  Union  can  get  a  Common  Rule  enforced  by 
the  law  of  the  land,  it  must  convince  the  community  at  large 
that  the  proposed  regulation  will  prove  advantageous  to  the 
state  as  a  whole,  and  not  unduly  burdensome  to  the  con- 
sumers. The  workmen's  grievance  has,  therefore,  to  be 
published  to  the  world,  to  bear  discussion  in  public  meetings, 
and  to  meet  the  criticism  of  the  newspapers.  Members  of 
Parliament  must  be  persuaded  to  take  the  matter  up,  and 
made  so  far  to  believe  in  the  justice  of  the  claim  as  to  be  will- 
ing to  importune  ministers  or  bore  the  House  of  Commons 
with  the  -subject.  In  due  course  a  Royal  Commission  is 
appointed,  which  hears  evidence,  collects  statistics,  and  makes 
a  report.  Presently  a  new  Factory  or  Mines  Bill  is  drafted 
by  the  Home  Secretary,  and,  on  the  combined  advice  of 

1  See  the  reports  of  the  various  Trade  Union  Congresses,  especially  since 
1885.  It  is  to  be  observed  that,  under  the  Constitution  of  the  United  States, 
most  of  the  statutes  thus  desired  by  English  Trade  Unionists,  like  much  of  the 
legislation  already  in  force,  might  be  held  void,  as  violations  of  the  constitutional 
right  of  freedom  of  contract.  Among  the  American  statutes  already  disallowed 
by  the  courts  on  this  ground  are  truck  acts,  acts  requiring  weekly  or  fortnightly 
pays,  or  forbidding  coalowners  to  compute  their  tonnage  rates  of  wages  on 
screened  coal  only,  acts  prohibiting  employers  from  discharging  men  merely 
because  they  are  Trade  Unionists,  and  a  factory  act  limiting  the  hours  of  labor 
of  adult  women.  See  Handbook  to  the  Labor  Law  of  the  United  States  (New 
York,  1896),  by  F.  J.  Stimson. 


254  Trade  Union  Function 

Government  inspectors,  medical  experts,  sympathetic  em- 
ployers, and,  perhaps,  a  few  representative  workmen,  some 
kind  of  clause  is  inserted  to  effect,  usually  not  what  the 
Trade  Union  has  been  asking  for,  but  the  minimum  which, 
in  the  light  of  all  the  evidence,  seems  indispensable  to  avert 
the  grossest  of  the  evil.  At  the  committee  stage  in  the 
House  of  Commons  the  clause  is  pulled  to  pieces  by  the 
spokesmen  of  the  employers  on  the  one  hand,  and  by  those 
of  the  workmen  on  the  other.  But  the  great  majority  of  the 
members  have,  like  the  minister  himself,  no  direct  interest  on 
either  side,  and  speak  rather  for  the  general  public  of  con- 
sumers anxious  to  "  keep  trade  in  the  country  "  and  foster 
cheapness,  than  with  a  view  to  secure  exceptional  advan- 
tages for  the  particular  section  concerned.  Thus  each  step 
has  to  be  gained  by  a  process  of  persuasion.  To  win  over 
in  succession  the  electors,  the  Members  of  Parliament,  the 
Ministers  of  the  Crown,  and — most  difficult  task  of  all — the 
permanent  professional  experts,  requires,  in  the  officers  of  a 
Trade  Union,  a  large  measure  of  statesmanship,  and,  in  the 
rank  and  file  of  the  members,  a  combination  of  wise  modera- 
tion, dogged  persistency,  steadfast  loyalty  to  leaders,  and 
"  sweet  reasonableness  "  at  a  compromise,  not  usually  charac- 
teristic of  popular  movements.  At  its  best  the  process  is 
a  slow  one.  The  Lancashire  "  Nine  Hours'  Movement,"  for 
instance,  attained,  perhaps,  a  more  rapid  and  complete  success 
than  any  other  agitation  for  factory  legislation.  Yet  it  cost 
the  Cotton-spinners  four  years'  expensive  and  harassing  work 
before  the  bill  reducing  the  factory  day  was  wrung  from  a, 
reluctant  legislature.1  On  the  other  hand,  the  "  Nine  Hours'' 
Day"  of  the  engineers,  gained  in  1871  by  the  Method  of 
Collective  Bargaining,  was  won  within  six  months  of  the  first 
negotiations  with  the  employers.2  Nor  is  the  victory  ever 
complete.  What  Parliament  ultimately  enacts  is  never  the 
full  measure  of  what  has  been  asked  for.  The  Cotton 
Operatives,  for  instance,  did  not  get  their  Nine  Hours'  Day, 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  295-298. 
2  Ibid.  pp.  299-302. 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  255 

but  only  a  56^  hours'  week.  By  the  Method  of  Collective 
Bargaining,  on  the  other  hand,  Trade  Unions  have  not 
infrequently  gained  from  employers,  at  times  of  strategic 
advantage,  not  only  the  whole  of  their  demands,  but  also  con- 
ditions so  exceptional  that  they  would  never  have  ventured 
to  embody  them  in  a  legislative  proposal.  We  shall  here- 
after see  how  this  consideration  deters  strong  Trade  Unions, 
like  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers  and  Iron  Ship- 
builders, from  going  to  Parliament  about  such  unsettled 
problems  as  Demarcation  of  Work  or  the  Limitation  of 
Apprentices,  on  which  they  feel  that  they  can  exact  better 
terms  than  would  be  conceded  to  them  by  the  community 
as  a  whole.  But  taking  merely  the  hours  of  labor  we  may 
note  how,  whilst  Parliament  has  not  yet  been  converted  even 
to  an  Eight  Hours'  Day  for  Miners,  the  coal-hewers  of  North- 
umberland and  Durham  have  long  since  secured  by  Collective 
Bargaining  a  working  day  for  themselves  of  less  than  7  hours, 
and  a  working  week  which  never  exceeds  37  hours. 

At  first  sight,  it  may  seem  strange  that,  in  face  of  all 
these  difficulties  and  disadvantages,  the  Trade  Unions  should 
so  persistently,  and  even  increasingly,  seek  for  legislative 
regulation  of  their  respective  industries.  The  explanation 
is  that,  however  tedious  and  difficult  may  be  the  process  of 
obtaining  it,  once  the  Common  Rule  is  embodied  in  an  Act  of 
Parliament,  it  satisfies  more  perfectly  the  Trade  Union  aspira- 
tions of  permanence  and  universality  than  any  other  method. 
It  is,  as  we  have  shown,  as  yet  rare  for  a  Trade  Union  to  have 
been  able  to  establish  by  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargain- 
ing anything  like  uniform  conditions  throughout  the  whole 
country.  Such  prominent  and  wealthy  unions,  for  instance^ 
as  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  and  the  Amal- 
gamated Society  of  Carpenters,  find  themselves  compelled 
to  recognise  hours  of  labor  varying,  in  different  towns,  from 
48  to  57  per  week  in  the  one  case,  and  from  41  to  60  in 
the  other.1 

1  The  Grays  and  Woolwich  Arsenal  branches  of  Engineers  among  others, 
stand  at  48   hours,  whilst  the  Vale  of  Leven  branch  works   57.     Among  the 


256  Trade  Union  Function 

But  even  where  any  Trade  Union  rule  exists,  either 
national  or  local,  there  are,  as  we  have  mentioned,  always 
some  extensive  districts,  and  some  important  establish- 
ments, in  which  the  rule  is  either  not  recognised  at  all,  or 
is  systematically  evaded.  An  Act  of  Parliament,  on  the 
contrary,  applies  uniformly  to  all  districts,  whether  the  Trade 
Union  is  strong  or  non-existent,  and  to  all  employers, 
whether  or  not  they  belong  to  the  Employers'  Association. 
It  corresponds,  in  fact,  to  the  ideal  form  of  Collective 
Bargaining,  a  National  Agreement  made  between  a  Trade 
Union  including  every  man  in  the  trade,  and  an  Employers' 
Association  from  which  no  firm  stands  aloof.  Like  such  an 
agreement  it  excludes,  from  influence  on  the  wage-contract, 
the  exigencies,  not  only  of  particular  workmen  or  particular 
establishments,  but  also  those  of  particular  districts.  But  it 
goes  a  stage  farther  in  this  direction.  A  National  Agree- 
ment, however  stable,  is  always  liable  to  be  changed,  in 
accordance  with  the  relative  strength  of  employers  and 
employed,  at  each  of  the  successive  inflations  and  depressions 
which  characterise  modern  industry.  The  Cotton-spinners, 
for  instance,  whose  standard  earnings  are  determined  by  an 
exceptionally  stable  National  Agreement,  have,  during  the 
last  twenty  years,  agreed  to  twelve  alterations  of  this  standard, 
five  times  upward  and  seven  downward.  But  once  any  part 
of  the  conditions  of  employment  has  been  deemed  of  suffi- 
cient importance  to  the  community  to  be  secured  by  law,  it 
is  beyond  the  reach  of  even  the  most  extreme  commercial 
crises.  In  the  blackest  days  of  1879,  when  many  cotton 
manufacturers  were  reduced  to  bankruptcy  and  the  operatives 
suffered  a  reduction  of  twenty  per  cent  of  their  wages,  no 
one  ever  suggested  that  the  expensive  statutory  requirements 
as  to  the  sanitation  of  the  factory,  or  the  fencing  of  dangerous 

Carpenters,  taking  the  mid-winter  hours,  the  Middleton  branch  works  41^  hours, 
the  Bury  branch  43^,  and  those  of  Prestwich  and  Radcliffe  44,  whilst  Yarmouth, 
Yeovil,  and  many  Irish  branches  are  still  at  60.  See  Statistics  of  Rates  of  Wages, 
etc.>  published  by  the  A.S.E.  in  1895,  and  the  Annual  Report  of  the  Amalgamates 
Society  of  Carpenters  for  1 894.  Compare,  too,  the  Reports  on  Wages  and 
of  Labour ;  published  by  the  Board  of  Trade,  C,  7567,  1894. 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  257 

machinery  should  be  relaxed.  In  our  History  of  Trade 
Unionism  we  have  shown  1  how  seriously,  in  these  years,  the 
Nine  Hours'  Day  of  the  engineering  and  building  trades 
secured  by  Collective  Bargaining,  was  nullified  by  the 
practice  of  systematic  overtime.  But  neither  inflation  nor 
depression  has,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  led  to  any  alteration 
since  1874  m  ^e  length  of  the  Cotton-spinners'  Normal  Day, 
which  the  Factory  Act  in  effect  prescribes.  The  Common 
Rule  embodied  in  an  Act  of  Parliament  has,  therefore, 
the  inestimable  advantage,  from  the  Trade  Union  point 
of  view,  of  being  beyond  the  influence  of  the  exigencies  of 
even  the  worst  times  of  depression.  And,  if  we  may  judge 
from  the  history  of  the  last  fifty  years,  such  a  rule  is  more 
apt  to  "  slide  up  "  than  to  "  slide  down."  Once  any  regula- 
tion has  been  adopted,  it  becomes  practically  impossible 
altogether  to  rescind  it,  whilst  the  movement  of  public 
opinion,  notably  on  such  matters  as  education,  sanitation, 
safety,  and  shorter  hours  of  labor,  has  been  steadily  in 
favor  of  increased  requirements  in  the  normal  Standard  of 
Life.2  These  characteristics  of  the  Method  of  Legal  Enact- 
ment have,  as  we  shall  see  in  subsequent  chapters,  an 
important  bearing  on  the  kind  of  Regulations  which  the 
Trade  Unionists  seek  to  enforce  by  this  particular  Method. 
But  before  we  consider  the  rules  themselves,  we  have  first  to 
describe  the  nature  and  extent  of  the  Trade  Union  machinery 
for  using  the  method. 

The  Trade  Unions  have  not  yet  developed,  for  their 
application  of  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment,  even  so 
much  formal  machinery  as  they  possess  for  the  Method  of 
Collective  Bargaining.  This  backwardness,  is,  in  the  main, 
to  be  attributed  to  the  difficulty  of  the  task.  The  dominant 
tendency  in  Trade  Union  history  is,  as  we  have  seen,  to 

1  Page  333. 

2  This  "partiality,"  however,  is  not  an  inherent  attribute  of  the  Method  of 
Legal  Enactment.      Its  existence  during  the  present  generation  is,  we  hold,  due 
to  the  shifting  of  political  power  from  the  middle  class,  who  had  become  opponents 
of  any  restriction  of  competition,   to  the  wage-earners,  who  have  continued  to 
believe  in  regulation. 

VOL.  I  S 


258  Trade  Union  Function 

make  the  trade  throughout  the  country  the  unit  of  organ- 
isation. But  to  bring  any  proposal  effectively  before  the 
legislature,  that  is  to  say,  to  persuade  members  of  Parliament 
to  take  the  matter  up,  Trade  Union  leaders  must  convert, 
not  the  employers  and  workmen  in  their  own  industry 
wherever  carried  on,  but  the  electors  of  particular  con- 
stituencies, to  whatever  trade  they  belong.  An  organisation 
according  to  localities  has,  therefore,  to  be  superposed  upon 
an  organisation  according  to  trades. 

Two  great  industries — cotton  and  coal — have  been  able 
to  surmount  this  difficulty,  and  these  alone  have  as  yet 
developed  any  effective  political  machinery.  The  powerful 
unions  of  Cotton  Operatives,  for  instance,  three-fourths  of 
whose  132,000  members  are  to  be  found  in  ten  constitu- 
encies within  twenty  miles  of  Bolton,  have,  during  the  past 
twenty -five  years,  constructed  a  special  organisation  for 
obtaining  and  enforcing  the  legislative  regulations  which 
they  desire.  The  five  societies  of  Spinners,  Weavers,  Card- 
room  Operatives,  Beamers,  and  Overlookers  are  federated 
in  the  United  Textile  Factory  Workers'  Association,  which 
carries  on  no  Collective  Bargaining,  and  possesses  no  insur- 
ance side,  but  has  for  its  sole  object  "  the  removal  of  any 
grievance  .  .  .  for  which  Parliamentary  or  Governmental 
interference  is  required."  l  The  Representative  Assembly 2 
of  this  federation,  consisting  of  nearly  200  delegates  from 
a  hundred  local  branches,  amalgamates  all  sections  of  the 
Cotton  Operatives  into  one  solid  union  for  their  common 
political  purposes.  But  it  is  the  Federal  Executive,8 
appointed  annually  by  this  Representative  Assembly,  that, 
governs  the  Parliamentary  policy  and  organises  the  political 
force  of  the  Trade.  This  Cabinet,  composed  in  the  main  of 
the  salaried  officials  of  the  separate  unions,  meets  regularly 
throughout  the  year,  exclusively  for  political  business.  At 
these  private  meetings,  held  in  the  parlor  of  a  Manchester 

1  Rules  of  1890. 

*  Called  the  "General  Council." 
8  Called  the  "Legislative  Council" 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  259 

public-house,  all  rhetoric  and  formality  is  banished,  and  the 
complaints  of  the  constituents  are  discussed  with  cynical 
shrewdness.  If  they  appear  to  admit  of  any  legislative  or 
administrative  remedy,  the  president  and  secretary — who 
are  invariably  leading  officials  of  the  Spinners  and  the 
Weavers  respectively — are  directed  to  take  the  matter  up. 
These  officers  are  wise  enough  to  call  in  expert  assistance. 
There  is  usually  some  eminent  lawyer  representing  a 
Lancashire  constituency,  who  is  glad  to  put  his  brains  freely 
at  the  disposal  of  so  influential  an  organisation.  A  clause 
or  a  bill  is  drafted,  and  communications  are  opened  up  with 
the  Home  Office.  Once  certain  of  the  technical  accuracy 
and  administrative  feasibility  of  the  proposals,  the  Federal 
Executive  opens  a  vigorous  political  campaign.  Public 
meetings  are  organised,  at  which  the  local  members  of 
Parliament,  or  in  default,  the  opposition  candidates,  are 
impartially  invited  to  preside.  By  these  meetings  not  only 
the  300,000  persons  employed  in  or  about  the  cotton  mills, 
but  also  the  other  electors,  and  the  Parliamentary  candidates 
themselves,  are  patiently  educated.  It  is  no  small  help  in 
this  process  that  the  Cotton  Operatives  have  what  is  virtually 
their  own  organ  in  the  press,  and  that  their  leading  officials 
write,  in  addition,  much  of  the  "  labor  news  "  in  the  provincial 
newspapers.  When  the  Parliamentary  session  opens,  the 
struggle  is  transferred  to  the  lobby  of  the  House  of  Commons. 
It  is  perhaps  a  fortunate  chance  that  the  present  general 
secretary  of  the  Spinners  belongs  to  the  Conservative  party, 
whilst  the  general  secretary  of  the  Weavers  is  a  staunch 
adherent  of  the  Liberals.  No  member  for  a  cotton  con- 
stituency, to  whichever  party  he  may  belong,  escapes  the 
pressure.  Meanwhile,  in  order  to  smooth  the  way  for 
legislation,  the  employers  will  have  been  approached  with 
a  view  to  arriving  at  some  common  policy  which  the  trade, 
as  a  whole,  can  press  on  the  Government.  The  millowners, 
for  instance,  will  be  persuaded  not  to  oppose  increased 
factory  regulation,  on  consideration  of  the  operatives  joining 
them  to  stop  a  threatened  Indian  import  duty,  or  combining 


260  Trade  Union  Function 

in  support  of  "  the  rehabilitation  of  silver."  When  a  general 
election  comes  near  an  urgent  appeal  is  issued  to  all  the 
132,000  members,  reminding  them  that  they  should  vote 
only  for  those  candidates,  of  whatever  political  party,  who 
promise  to  support  the  trade  programme.  No  one  can  read 
the  frequent  circulars,  the  minutes  of  the  conferences  with 
employers  and  members  of  Parliament,  the  reports  of  the 
public  meetings,  dinners  to  factory  inspectors  and  deputa- 
tions to  the  Home  Office,  the  leading  articles  in  the  Cotton 
Factory  Times,  and  the  "  questions  to  candidates  "  for  election 
in  Lancashire  constituencies,  without  admitting  that  the 
Cotton  Operatives  have  known  how  to  construct  a  political 
machine  of  remarkable  efficiency.  The  result  is  that  the 
legislative  regulation  of  the  Cotton  trade  has  been  carried 
to  a  point  far  in  advance  of  any  other  industry,  whilst  the 
law  is  enforced  with  a  stringent  regularity  unknown  in  other 
districts.1 

In  the  case  of  the  Cotton  Operatives  the  close  observer 
may  suspect  that  the  political  machinery  is  better  than  the 
material  out  of  which  it  is  made.  Absorbed  in  chapels  and 
co-operative  stores,  eager  by  individual  thrift  to  rise  out  of 
the  wage-earning  class,  and  accustomed  to  adopt  the  views 
of  the  local  millowners  and  landlords,  the  Cotton  Operatives, 
as  a  class,  are  not  remarkable  for  political  capacity.  In  the 
interest  that  they  take  in  public  affairs  they  are  behind  the 
coalminers  of  the  North  and  Midland  districts  of  England. 
Among  these  underground  workers  the  instinct  for  democratic 
politics  is  so  keen  that  they  have,  for  over  twenty  years,  sent 
their  own  officials  to  represent  them  in  the  House  of  Commons. 
Like  the  Cotton  Operatives  they  have  exceptional  political 
opportunities,  four -fifths  of  the  whole  membership  being 
massed  in  a  relatively  small  number  of  Parliamentary  con- 
stituencies. These  advantages  are,  however,  largely  neutral- 
ised by  the  fact  that  they  are,  for  political  purposes,  divided 

1  The  meetings  of  the  United  Textile  Factory  Operatives'  Association  were 
temporarily  suspended  in  1896,  the  officials  stating  that  the  time  was  inopportune 
for  any  further  extension  of  factory  legislation. 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  261 

into  two  hostile  factions,  the  Miners'  Federation  on  the  one 
hand,  and  the  county  unions  of  Northumberland  and  Durham 
on  the  other. 

The  miners  of  Northumberland  and  Durham  were,  for 
over  a  generation,  the  pioneers  and  energetic  leaders  of  the 
movement  in  favor  of  the  legal  regulation  of  the  conditions 
of  labor  in  the  mine.  We  need  not  again  describe  the 
machinery  of  the  active  legal  and  Parliamentary  campaigns 
between  1843  and  1887.  From  the  appointment  of  the 
"  Miners'  Attorney-General "  down  to  the  death  of  Alexander 
Macdonald,  the  promoters  of  the  successive  Mines  Regulation 
Acts  drew  their  strongest  support  from  the  two  Northern 
counties.  We  have  described  elsewhere *  the  curious  com- 
bination of  industrial  circumstances  and  economic  theories 
which  have  brought  the  Northumberland  and  Durham  unions 
to  a  standstill  as  regards  the  legal  regulation  of  their  trade. 
They  still  nominally  retain  a  separate  political  machinery 
under  the  name  of  the  National  Union  of  Miners.2  But  the 
effective  political  influence  of  the  miners  of  these  counties  is 
now  expressed  mainly  by  their  three  officials  having  seats  in 
the  House  of  Commons.  These  members,  in  conjunction 
with  the  leading  local  officials  of  the  Northumberland  and 
Durham  Unions,  object  to  the  extension  of  legal  regulation, 
and  actively  oppose  the  Eight  Hours'  Bill. 

The  great  bulk  of  the  miners  have,  however,  retained 
their  belief  in  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment,  and  are  to-day 
even  more  persistent  than  their  fathers  in  demanding  its 
further  application.  The  Miners'  Federation  of  Great  Britain 
(established  1887,  and  now  counting  200,000  members), 
which  we  described  in  our  chapter  on  "The  Unit  of  Govern- 
ment," is  essentially  a  political  organisation.  It  deals,  it  is 
true,  also  with  Collective  Bargaining,  in  so  far  as  anything 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  284-292,  377-380. 

2  This  federal  body,  formed  by  Alexander  Macdonald  exclusively  for  Parlia- 
mentary  purposes,  once  included  practically  all  the  miners'  unions  in  the  kingdom, 
and  was,  in  its  time,  the  most  influential  political  organisation  in  the  Trade 
Union  world.     To-day  it  is  confined  to  the  two  unions  of  Northumberland  and 
Durham,  and  retains  only  a  shadowy  separate  existence. 


262  Trade  Union  Function 

approaching  to  a  National  Agreement  is  concerned.  But  all 
the  ordinary  business  of  Mutual  Insurance  and  Collective 
Bargaining  is  performed  by  the  separate  county  unions,  and 
nine-tenths  of  the  federal  work  relates,  like  that  of  the  United 
Textile  Factory  Workers'  Association,  to  matters  in  which 
legislative  or  governmental  interference  is  required.  Like  the 
Cotton  Operatives,  too,  the  Miners'  Federation  acts  through  a 
Representative  Assembly  and  an  Executive  which  is  virtually 
a  cabinet  of  the  salaried  officials  of  the  constituent  Unions. 
It  is  a  matter  of  common  knowledge  that  this  organisation 
exercises  great  political  power,  and  it  is,  in  Parliamentary 
influence,  second  only  to  the  United  Textile  Factory  Workers' 
Association.  In  one  respect  it  is  even  stronger.  Owing  to 
the  loyalty  of  the  miners  to  their  leaders,  and  to  their  demo- 
cratic fervor,  the  Parliamentary  and  local  elections  in  mining 
constituencies  may  be  said  to  be  entirely  controlled  by  the 
miners'  organisations.  No  candidate  can  be  elected  who 
does  not  support  their  programme.  It  is  in  the  manipula- 
tion of  both  political  parties  in  the  House  of  Commons  that 
the  Miners  fall  behind  the  Cotton  Operatives.  The  Miners' 
Federation  has,  in  the  first  place,  to  struggle  against  the  very 
serious  obstacle  presented  by  the  resolute  hostility  of  the 
Northumberland  and  Durham  unions.  In  the  Parliament  of 
1892-95  if  Mr.  Pickard  or  Mr.  Woods  proposed  some  measure 
desired  by  the  Miners'  Federation,  he  was  pretty  sure  to  be 
answered  not  by  an  employer,  but  by  Mr.  Burt  or  Mr. 
Fenwick,  speaking  for  the  miners  of  the  two  Northern 
counties.  The  fact  too,  that  all  the  miners'  representatives 
in  the  House  of  Commons  are  loyal  supporters  of  one  political 
party  interferes,  to  some  extent,  with  their  influence  both  with 
that  party  and  with  its  opponents.  And  although  this  great 
federation  can  count  among  its  officials  men  of  ability, 
experience,  and  unquestioned  integrity,  we  are  inclined  to 
doubt  whether  the  general  level  of  technical  and  economic 
knowledge  among  them  is  quite  as  high  as  that  of  the  staff 
of  the  Cotton  Operatives,  recruited  as  the  latter  is  by 
competitive  examination.  It  is,  perhaps,  due  to  this  fact  that 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  263 

the  Miners'  officials  do  not  as  yet  realise  the  necessity  of 
expert  legal  and  Parliamentary  counsel  in  their  deliberations, 
and  make  far  less  use  than  the  Cotton  Operatives  of  outside 
help.  They  have  no  intercourse  with  the  Government  Mines 
Inspectors,  and,  unlike  the  Cotton  Operatives,  they  do  not 
enjoy  the  advantage  of  constantly  meeting,  on  terms  of  easy 
equality,  the  salaried  officers  of  the  employers'  associations. 
Moreover,  they  have  no  organ  of  their  own  in  the  press,  and 
they  seldom  contribute  to  other  newspapers.  Strong  in  their 
numbers  and  their  concentrated  electoral  power,  the  Miners 
have,  in  fact,  hitherto  somewhat  suffered  from  their  isolation. 
But  notwithstanding  all  these  drawbacks,  the  steady  improve- 
ment and  progressive  elaboration  of  the  Mines  Regulation 
Acts,  in  the  face  of  powerful  capitalist  opposition,  bears 
eloquent  testimony  to  the  past  and  present  effectiveness  of 
the  Miners'  political  organisations. 

No  trade  society  other  than  those  connected  with  cotton 
and  coal  has  developed  any  effective  machinery  for  obtaining 
the  legal  regulations  which  are  demanded  by  its  members. 
This  is,  in  some  cases,  to  be  attributed  to  the  absence,  among 
the  rank  and  file,  of  any  keen  desire  for  special  Acts  of 
Parliament.  Some  powerful  unions,  like  the  United  Society 
of  Boilermakers,  which  enforces  a  rigid  limit  on  the  number 
of  apprentices,  are  comparatively  indifferent  to  the  law  as  an 
instrument  for  obtaining  the  conditions  of  labor  that  they 
desire.  But  there  are  other  trades  which  feel,  even  more 
strongly  than  the  Cotton  Operatives  and  Miners,  their 
dependence  on  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  as  the  only 
effective  way  of  securing  what  they  consider  fair  conditions 
of  employment.  Not  to  mention  such  modern  organisations 
as  those  of  the  Gasworkers  and  Seamen,  whose  objects  are 
mainly  legislative,  we  watch  old-established  unions  like  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Tailors,  the  several  societies  of 
cutlery  workers  of  Sheffield,  and  the  Hosiers  of  the  Midland 
Counties  all  basing  their  aspirations  on  the  legal  regulation 
of  homework,  and  the  prohibition  of  insidious  forms  of 
"truck."  Typical  "old  unionists"  like  the  Ironfounders, 


264  Trade  Union  Function 

Stonemasons,  and  Engineers  are  constantly  voting  by  large 
majorities  in  favor  of  drastic  legal  enactments  providing  for 
the  better  sanitation  of  their  workplaces,  for  additional  pre- 
cautions against  accidents,  for  the  compulsory  compensation 
of  those  who  suffer  through  negligence,  for  the  adoption  in 
all  public  contracts  of  the  Standard  Rates  of  Wages,  and  last, 
but  in  recent  years  not  least,  for  the  suppression  of  overtime, 
and  the  maintenance  of  a  Legal  Day.  And  yet  it  is  not  too 
much  to  say  that,  as  regards  all  these  points,  the  organised 
Trade  Unions,  with  their  hundreds  of  thousands  of  electors, 
exercise,  to-day,  practically  no  appreciable  influence  on  the 
House  of  Commons  and,  unlike  the  Cotton  Operatives  and 
Miners,  have  not  learnt  either  to  supplement  the  efforts  of 
sympathetic  philanthropists,  or  to  strengthen  the  hands  of 
willing  politicians.  The  problem  of  superposing  an  organisa- 
tion according  to  locality  upon  one  according  to  trades,  has, 
in  fact,  proved  too  complicated  for  Trade  Union  statesman- 
ship. 

We  shall  best  understand  this  failure  by  considering  first 
the  difficulties  that  prevent  any  single  trade  from  attaining 
political  influence,  and  then  the  kind  of  organisation  by  which 
such  difficulties  might  be  overcome.  The  typical  Trade 
Union  has  its  members  scattered  in  small  groups,  each  of 
which  makes  up  a  tiny  fraction  of  an  electoral  constituency. 
The  adult  male  Cotton  Operatives  of  Oldham  practically 
dominate  the  local  electorate,  but  the  Oldham  Plumbers 
number  only  69,  and  the  Oldham  Carpenters  only  152 
— contingents  too  small  to  be  able  to  impress  their  views 
on  Parliamentary  candidates.  At  Morpeth  again,  the  Coal- 
miners  have,  for  over  twenty  years,  been  able  to  actually 
return  one  of  their  own  officials  as  the  member.  But  the 
Morpeth  Tailors  number  only  five,  and  are  thus  practically 
helpless.  Even  in  London,  where  the  Amalgamated  Society 
of  Tailors  dominates  its  own  skilled  branch  of  the  trade,  its 
two  thousand  members  are  spread  over  sixty  constituencies. 
It  is  evident  that  the  only  way  by  which  the  men  engaged 
in  such  widely  dispersed  industries  as  building  and  tailoring 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  265 

can  force  their  grievances  on  an  ignorant  public  or  a  reluctant 
Parliament,  is  by  combined  action  among  the  different  trades 
of  each  constituency.  Even  the  Engineers,  who  are  in  certain 
centres  aggregated  in  large  numbers,  are  politically  weakened 
in  their  own  strongholds  by  their  division  into  sectional 
societies.  And  joint  action  is  even  more  clearly  necessary 
in  the  case  of  the  great  number  of  little  local  trades,  which 
have  not  the  compensation  of  numerous  branches  and  a  large 
aggregate  membership.  Now,  the  long  and  varied  experience 
of  the  Cotton  Operatives  and,  to  a  lesser  extent,  that  of  the 
Coalminers  prove  that  if  a  political  federation  is  to  be 
successful,  three  conditions  are  absolutely  indispensable. 
There  must,  in  the  first  place,  be  a  vigorous  central  executive, 
to  which  is  entrusted  the  entire  direction  of  all  the  pro- 
ceedings. In  effective  connection  with  this  central  committee, 
there  must  be  local  organisations  in  the  various  constituencies, 
always  prompt  to  obey  the  directions  of  the  leaders,  and  to 
subordinate  other  interests  to  the  main  object.  Finally,  the 
central  committee  must  not  only  have  in  its  service  an 
adequate  staff  of  able  men  as  officials,  but  must  also  know 
how  to  command,  either  for  love  or  money,  and  be  willing 
frequently  to  use,  the  professional  advice  of  trained  experts  in 
law,  in  Parliamentary  procedure,  in  administration,  and  in 
what  may  be  called  general  politics. 

It  may  at  first  be  thought  that,  in  the  annual  Trade 
Union  Congress,  the  Parliamentary  Committee,  and  the  local 
Trades  Councils,  the  Trade  Union  world  possesses  a  political 
machinery  fulfilling  these  elementary  conditions.  There  is  a 
Representative  Assembly,  to  which  nearly  every  organised 
trade  sends  delegates.  This  assembly  has  nothing  to  do 
with  Mutual  Insurance  or  Collective  Bargaining,  and  deals 
exclusively  with  the  political  interests  of  the  Trade  Union 
world.  It  elects  a  Cabinet  of  thirteen  members,  on  which 
sit  some  of  the  ablest  salaried  officers  of  the  movement. 
The  duty  of  this  "  Parliamentary  Committee "  is  expressly 
defined  to  be  "to  watch  all  legislative  measures  directly 
affecting  the  question  of  Labor,  to  initiate  such  legislative 


266  Trade  Union  Function 

action  as  Congress  may  direct,  and  to  prepare  the  programme 
for  the  Congress."  1  Finally  there  exist,  in  over  a  hundred 
towns,  which  together  elect  a  third  of  the  House  of  Commons, 
joint  committees  of  the  local  Trade  Union  branches,  formed 
"  to  watch  over  the  general  interests  of  Labor — political  and 
social — both  in  and  out  of  Parliament."2  But  a  short 
examination  of  the  constitution  and  working  of  this  organ- 
isation will,  we  think,  make  clear  that,  whatever  outward 
resemblances  to  an  effective  political  machine  it  may  pos- 
sess, it  lacks  all  the  essential  conditions  of  efficiency  and 
success. 

Let  us,  to  begin  with,  take  the  Parliamentary  Committee, 
upon  which,  to  follow  the  analogy  of  the  Cotton  Operatives, 
should  fall  the  duties  of  formulating  a  national  Trade  Union 
programme,  of  guiding  the  deliberations  of  the  Trade  Union 
Congress,  of  directing  the  necessary  political  campaign 
throughout  the  constituencies,  and  finally,  of  conducting  the 
desired  measures  through  Parliament.  But  the  Parliamentary 
Committee  has,  for  the  last  twenty  years,  had  practically  no 
means  of  fulfilling  these  functions.  The  central  executives 
of  the  unions,  from  whom  alone  any  responsible  statement  of 
the  trade  grievances  and  proposals  can  be  obtained,  seldom 
dream  of  communicating  their  desires  to  the  Parliamentary 
Committee,  This  has  naturally  followed  from  the  fact  that 
there  is  no  central  staff  able  to  cope  with  such  proposals  as 
have  from  time  to  time  come  in.3  For  all  the  Parliamentary 
and  other  business  of  the  Trade  Union  world  as  a  whole, 
there  is  provided  only  a  single  secretary,  who  is  usually  one 
of  the  "  Labor  Representatives  "  in  the  House  of  Commons, 

1  Amended    Standing    Orders,    drawn    up    by    Parliamentary    Committee, 
November  1894. 

2  Rules  of  the  London  Trades  Council,  revised  March  1895.     The  Manchester 
and  Salford  Trades  Council  (established  1866)  declares  that  its  objects  are  "to 
watch  over  the   social  and  political   rights  and  interests  of  Labor,    local  and 
national,  but  not  of  party  political  character.      Its  duties  shall  be  to  direct  the 
power  and  influence  possessed  by  its  constituents,  in  promoting  and  supporting 
such  measures  as  may  appear  likely  to  increase  the  comfort  and  happiness  of  the 
people,  and  generally  to  assist  in  securing  the  ends  for  which  Trade  Unions  were 
called  into  existence."     (Report  for  1890.) 

3  Histcry  of  Trade  Unionism^  pp.  356-358,  470-474. 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  267 

with  prior  duties  to  his  own  constituency.  For  the  last  five 
years  the  occupant  of  the  post  has  been  a  salaried  official  of 
his  own  union,  busily  occupied  with  its  particular  sectional 
interests.  The  Parliamentary  Committee  admittedly  pays 
only  for  the  leavings  of  his  time  and  attention,  a  large  part 
of  the  salary  of  £200  1  going,  in  fact,  to  the  son  or  friend 
who  does  the  routine  office  work  during  his  frequent  absences 
from  London.  It  is  therefore  impossible  for  the  Parlia- 
mentary Committee  to  investigate  grievances,  or  to  form  an 
independent  judgment  on  technical  proposals.  The  members 
of  the  Committee  are,  no  doubt,  severally  quite  competent  to 
deal  with  their  own  trades,  but  for  the  Committee  as  a  whole 
to  act  on  this  assumption  necessarily  means  its  implicit 
acceptance  of  the  technical  proposals  of  any  one  of  its 
members.  As  regards  the  vast  majority  of  unrepresented 
trades  the  Committee  has  absolutely  no  means  of  ascertaining, 
either  what  is  complained  of,  or  what  remedies  are  practicable. 
Nor  does  it  ever  occur  to  the  Parliamentary  Committee  to 
attempt  to  make  up  for  this  deficiency  by  seeking  expert  or 
professional  advice,  for  which  Congress  has  never  been  asked 
to  provide  funds.  We  despair  of  making  any  middle-class 
student  realise  the  strength  and  persistency  of  this  disinclina- 
tion of  Trade  Unionists  to  call  in  outside  counsel.  A  Board 
of  Railway  Directors  or  a  Town  Council  do  not  imagine 
that  they  are  bartering  their  independence  or  impairing  their 
dignity  when  they  consult  an  engineer  or  a  solicitor,  or  when 
they  employ  an  actuary  or  a  Parliamentary  draughtsman. 
Though  they  are  themselves  what  the  Trade  Unionists  would 
call  "  practical  men  "  they  invariably  commit  even  their  own 
proposals  to  professional  experts  to  be  critically  examined 
and  put  into  proper  form.  But  owing,  we  believe,  to  a 
combination  of  sturdy  independence,  naYve  self-complacency, 
and  an  extremely  narrow  outlook  on  affairs,  the  Parliamentary 
Committee,  like  most  Trade  Union  organisations,  apparently 
regard  themselves  as  competent  to  be  their  own  solicitors, 
their  own  actuaries,  and  even  their  own  Parliamentary 

1  Raised,  in  1896,  to  ,£300. 


268  Trade  Union  Function 

draughtsmen.1       It    is    unnecessary    to    add    that,    in    each 
capacity,  they  attain  the  proverbial  result. 

Any  idea  of  intellectual  leadership  of  the  Trade  Union 
world  has  accordingly  long  since  been  abandoned  by  the 
Parliamentary  Committee.  This  has  entailed  the  degenera- 
tion of  the  Trade  Union  Congress.  The  four  or  five  hundred 
members  coming  from  all  trades  and  parts  of  the  kingdom 
are  largely  unknown  to  each  other  and  new  to  their  work. 
Each  delegate  brings  to  the  meeting  his  own  pet  ideas  and 
legislative  projects.  In  order  to  make  such  a  Representative 
Assembly  into  a  useful  piece  of  democratic  machinery,  the 
first  requisite  is  a  strong  "  Front  Bench "  of  responsible 
leaders,  who  have  themselves  arrived  at  a  definite  and  con- 
sistent policy.  But  this,  as  we  have  seen,  is  beyond  the 
capacity  of  the  Parliamentary  Committee  in  its  present  lack 
of  information,  staff,  and  expert  counsel.  What  happens,  in 
fact,  is  that  a  few  stock  resolutions  are  moved  by  members 
of  the  Committee,  but  nine-tenths  of  the  time  of  Congress  is 
given  to  the  casual  proposals  sent  in  by  the  rank  and  file. 
These  are  not  examined  or  reported  on  by  the  Parliamentary 
Committee,  or  even  referred  for  consideration  to  special 
committees  elected  for  the  purpose.  They  appear  higgledy- 
piggledy  in  the  agenda  of  the  Congress  sitting  as  a  whole, 
the  order  in  which  they  are  discussed  being  decided  by  lot.2 
The  bewildered  delegates,  fresh  from  the  bench  or  the  mine, 
find  themselves  confronted  with  a  hundred  and  fifty  hetero- 
geneous proposals,  some  containing  highly  technical  amend- 
ments of  the  statutes  relating  to  particular  trades,  others 
being  mere  pious  aspirations  for  social  amelioration,  and 
others,  again,  involving  far-reaching  changes  in  the  economic 
and  political  constitution  of  the  country.  All  these  come 
before  Congress  with  equal  authority  ;  are  explained  in  five- 

1  We  have  already  mentioned  that  the  United  Textile  Factory  Workers' 
Association  is  honorably  distinguished  among  Trade  Unions  for  its  freedom  from 
this  defect.     The  Co-operative  and  Friendly  Society  Movements  have,  to  a  large 
extent,  learnt  a  similar  lesson. 

2  Some  improvement  has  been  made  in  this  respect  during  the  last  year  or 
two,  the  notices  of  motion  being  now  classified  according  to  their  subjects. 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  269 

minute  speeches  ;  and  as  regards  four  out  of  every  five,  get 

deliberative  assembly  checking  and  ratifying  a  programme 
prepared,  after  careful  investigation,  by  a  responsible  Cabinet, 
the  Trade  Union  Congress  is  now  an  unorganised  public  meet- 
ing, utterly  unable  to  formulate  any  consistent  or  practical 
policy. 

In  the  absence  alike  of  an  effective  central  executive,  and 
of  any  definite  programme,  it  is  of  minor  import  that  the 
joint  committees  which  should  act  in  the  several  constituencies 
are  themselves  inefficient,  and  completely  divorced  from  the 
other  parts  of  the  machine.  We  do  not  need  to  repeat  our 
detailed  description  and  working  of  the  Trades  Councils.3  It 
is  obvious  that  if  such  Councils  are  to  be  of  any  use  in 
influencing  the  constituencies,  they  must  receive  the  confidence 
and  support  of  the  central  executive  of  each  trade,  and 
strictly  co-ordinate  all  their  political  action  with  that  of  the 
Parliamentary  Committee.  But  for  reasons  on  which  we 
have  elsewhere  dwelt,  the  central  executives  of  the  national 
trade  societies  view  with  suspicion  and  jealousy  the  very 
existence  of  local  committees  over  whose  action  they  have 
no  control.  The  Parliamentary  Committee,  which  ought  to 
exercise  that  control,  has,  in  the  absence  of  a  real  programme 
and  of  anything  like  an  office  staff,  for  many  years  given  up 
all  attempts  to  direct,  or  even  to  influence,  the  bodies  through 
which  alone  it  could  conduct  an  effective  electoral  campaign. 
Without  leadership,  without  an  official  programme, and  without 
any  definite  work,  the  Trades  Councils  have  become,  in  effect, 
microscopic  Trade  Union  Congresses,  with  all  the  deficiencies 
of  unorganised  public  meetings.  Their  wild  and  inconsistent 
resolutions,  no  less  than  their  fitful  and  erratic  action,  have 
naturally  increased  the  dislike  of  the  central  executives,  and 
of  the  salaried  officials  who  dominate  the  Parliamentary 
Committee.  Since  1895  they  have  even  been  excluded 
from  participation  in  the  Trade  Union  Congress.  Thus 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  467-470, 
2  Ibid.  pp.  440-444,  466,  467. 


270  Trade  Union  Function 

there  is  now  no  working  connection  between  the  central  com- 
mittee and  the  organisations  in  the  several  constituencies. 

We  see  therefore  that,  notwithstanding  a  great  parade  of 
political  influence,  the  Trade  Union  world,  as  a  whole,  is 
really  without  an  organised  machinery  for  using  the  Method 
of  Legal  Enactment.  This  outcome  of  thirty  years'  effort 
may  well  lead  to  doubts  whether  it  is  practicable  to  construct 
efficient  machinery  for  the  political  business  of  the  whole 
Trade  Union  world.  Some  persons  may  suggest  that  the  ex- 
perience of  the  Cotton  Operatives  and  the  Coalminers  points 
rather  to  the  development  of  separate  political  machinery 
for  each  great  group  of  industries.  On  this  assumption 
we  should  have  political  federations  of  the  Engineering  and 
Shipbuilding  trades,  of  the  various  branches  of  the  Clothing 
Trade,  of  the  Building  and  Furniture  Trades,  and  perhaps 
even  of  the  Transport  Workers  and  the  General  Laborers. 
But  whether  the  machinery  for  using  the  Method  of  Legal 
Enactment  covers  the  whole  Trade  Union  world,  or  is  con- 
fined to  particular  sections,  it  will  not  be  possible  for  it  to 
obtain  even  such  success  as  has  been  won  by  the  Cotton 
Operatives  and  the  Coalminers  without  a  radical  change  in 
spirit,  if  not  also  in  form.  It  may  safely  be  predicted  that 
no  Parliamentary  organisation  of  the  Trade  Union  world  will 
be  politically  effective  until  the  narrow  limits  of  its  action  are 
definitely  recognised,  and  until  the  separate  functions  of  the 
Central  Federal  Executive,  the  Representative  Assembly, 
and  the  Local  Councils  are  clearly  understood,  and  placed  in 
proper  co-ordination  with  each  other. 

Let  us  first  consider  the  importance  of  recognising  the 
narrow  limits  within  which  such  political  influence  must  be 
exercised.  We  have  here,  in  fact,  a  particular  application 
of  the  principles  upon  which,  as  we  showed  in  our  chapter 
on  "  Interunion  Relations,"  any  combined  action  must  be 
based.  The  paramount  condition  of  stable  federation  is,  as 
we  have  suggested,  that  the  constituent  bodies  should  be 
united  only  in  so  far  as  they  possess  interests  in  common, 
and  that  in  respect  of  all  other  matters  they  should  retain 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  2  7 1 

their  independence.  The  Trade  Union  Congress  is  a  federa- 
tion for  obtaining,  by  Parliamentary  action,  not  social  reform 
generally,  but  the  particular  measures  desired  by  its  constituent 
Trade  Unions.1  These  all  desire  certain  measures  of  legal 
regulation  confined  to  their  own  particular  trades,  and  they 
are  prepared,  if  this  limitation  is  observed,  to  back  up  each 
other's  demands.  On  many  important  subjects,  such  as  Free- 
dom of  Combination,  Compensation  for  Accidents,  Truck,  Sani- 
tation, "  the  Particulars  Clause,"  the  weekly  payment  of  wages, 
and  the  abolition  of  disciplinary  fines,  they  are  united  on 
general  measures.  But  directly  the  Congress  diverges  from 
its  narrow  Trade  Union  function,  and  expresses  any  opinion, 
either  on  general  social  reforms  or  party  politics,  it  is  bound 
to  alienate  whole  sections  of  its  constituents.  The  Trade 
Unions  join  the  Congress  for  the  promotion  of  a  Parlia- 
mentary policy  desired,  not  merely  by  a  majority,  but  by  all 
of  them  ;  and  it  is  a  violation  of  the  implied  contract  between 
them  to  use  the  political  force,  towards  the  creation  of  which 
all  are  contributing,  for  the  purposes  of  any  particular  political 
party.  The  Trade  Unionists  of  Northumberland  and  Durham 
are  predominantly  Liberal.  Those  of  Lancashire  are  largely 
Conservative.  Those  of  Yorkshire  and  London,  again,  are 
deeply  impregnated  with  Socialism.  If  the  Congress  adopts 
the  Shibboleths,  or  supports  the  general  policy  of  any  of 
the  three  parties  which  now — on  questions  outside  Trade 
Unionism — divide  the  allegiance  of  British  workmen,  its 
influence  is  at  once  destroyed.  The  history  of  the  Trade 
Union  Congress  during  the  last  twenty  years  emphatically 
confirms  this  view.  Whether  it  is  "  captured  "  by  the 
Liberals  (as  in  1878-85)  or  by  the  Socialists  (as  in  1893-94); 
whether  it  is  pledged  to  Peasant  Proprietorship  or  to  Land 
Nationalisation  ;  whether  it  declares  in  favor  of  Bimetal- 
lism or  the  "  Nationalisation  of  the  means  of  production, 

1  In  the  course  of  our  subsequent  analysis  of  the  Trade  Union  Regulations 
themselves,  and  in  our  final  survey,  we  shall  discover  the  political  programme  for 
the  Trade  Union  world.  See  the  chapters  on  "  The  Economic  Characteristics 
of  Trade  Unionism  "  and  "  Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy." 


272  Trade  Union  Function 

distribution,  and  exchange,"  it  equally  destroys  its  capacity 
for  performing  its  proper  work,  and  provokes  a  reaction 
which  nullifies  its  political  influence. 

Once  this  limitation  were  understood  and  definitely 
recognised,  it  would  become  possible  to  weld  the  separate 
parts  of  the  existing  Trade  Union  organisation  into  a  political 
machinery  of  considerable  influence.  The  first  requisite 
would  be  a  central  federal  committee,  meeting  exclusively 
for  the  definite  political  purposes  which  we  have  indicated. 
To  this  Parliamentary  Committee  the  central  executive  of 
each  national  trade  would  bring  its  particular  grievances, 
with  the  remedies  proposed,  just  as  the  Weavers'  executive 
submits  to  the  United  Textile  Factory  Workers'  Association 
its  objections  to  over- steaming  and  its  proposals  for  the 
abolition  of  this  practice.  On  no  account  must  any  proposal 
be  taken  up  by  the  Parliamentary  Committee  which  had  not 
received  the  express  endorsement  of  the  central  executive  of 
the  trade  concerned.  Any  departure  from  this  rule  would 
bring  the  federal  committee  into  conflict  with  its  real  con- 
stituents, and  deprive  it  of  all  guarantee  that  the  proposal 
had  been  accepted  by  the  bulk  of  the  members  most  directly 
to  be  affected.  But  this  endorsement  would  not  in  itself 
suffice.  The  Parliamentary  Committee,  acting  in- conjunction 
with  the  officers  of  the  trade  concerned,  would  have  to  take 
expert  advice  as  to  the  extent  of  the  grievance,  the  practica- 
bility of  the  remedy  proposed,  and  the  best  form  in  which  it 
could  be  put.  The  approved  legislative  proposals  of  the 
several  trades  could  then  be  marshalled  into  a  precise  and 
consistent  Parliamentary  programme,  from  which  all  vague 
aspirations  or  rhetorical  claptrap  would  be  excluded.  When 
the  programme  for  the  year  had,  after  careful  investigation 
and  thought,  at  last  been  framed,  it  would  have  to  be  pre- 
sented to  a  Representative  Assembly  of  all  the  trades.  In 
emphatic  contrast  with  the  practice  of  the  present  Trade 
Union  Congress,  it  should  be  made  a  cardinal  rule  that  no 
proposition  for  political  action  should  be  brought  before  the 
Assembly,  unless  it  had  first  been  submitted  to  the  Parlia- 


Tke  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  273 

mentary  Committee  for  investigation  and  report.  With  such 
a  rule  the  delegates  from  each  trade  would  find  before  them 
the  proposals  which  had  been  sent  up  by  their  executives, 
couched  in  the  best  possible  language,  and  recommended  to 
the  delegates  of  the  other  trades  by  the  cumulative  authority 
of  the  officials  of  the  industry  concerned,  the  skilled  political 
staff  of  the  Parliamentary  Committee  itself,  and  the  legal  and 
administrative  experts  who  had  been  consulted.  At  this 
stage,  discussion  by  all  the  trades  would  serve  to  reveal  any 
latent  divergence  of  interest  or  policy  which  would  militate 
against  the  electoral  success  of  even  a  perfectly  devised 
programme.  But  such  an  assembly  would  fulfil  a  much 
more  important  purpose  than  merely  amending  and  ratify- 
ing an  official  programme.  It  would  enable  the  leaders  to 
explain  the  several  items,  and  demonstrate  to  the  whole 
Trade  Union  world  their  necessity,  adequacy,  and  consistency 
with  the  common  interests  of  all  Trade  Unionists. 

The  programme  once  settled,  the  work  of  political 
agitation  would  begin.  Here  the  Parliamentary  Committee 
would  have  to  be  supplemented  by  a  local  federation  in  each 
constituency.  This  local  body  would  naturally  be  formed, 
like  the  present  Trades  Councils,  of  representatives  from  all 
the  Trade  Union  branches  in  the  constituency,  or  in  the 
town.  It  would  be  vital  to  its  efficiency  and  success  that 
the  central  executives  of  the  several  trades  should  regard  its 
constitution  as  of  national  importance  to  them  ;  urge  their 
branches  to  elect  their  most  responsible  members  ;  and  give 
them  every  encouragement  to  contribute  their  quota  of  the 
local  expenses  from  the  society's  funds.  It  goes  without 
saying  that  these  local  councils  must,  no  less  strictly  than 
the  Trade  Union  Congress,  avoid  all  bias  in  favor  of  one  or 
other  political  party,  and  confine  themselves  rigidly  to  Trade 
Union  objects.  But  their  proceedings  must  be  subject  to  a 
yet  narrower  limit.  Unlike  the  existing  Trades  Councils, 
they  must  realise  that  it  is  no  part  of  their  business  to 
frame  the  Parliamentary  programme  even  in  matters  on 
which  all  their  constituent  branches  are  unanimous.  This 
VOL.  I  T 


274  Trade  Union  Function 

follows  from  the  fact  that  each  trade  must  be  dealt  with  as  a 
national  unit.  Before  the  Engineers  or  the  Tailors  can  hope 
to  get  any  amendment  of  the  law  relating  to  their  trade,  all 
the  branches  from  one  end  of  the  kingdom  to  the  other  must 
be  prepared  to  back  up  an  identical  demand ;  and  the 
demand  must  be  formulated  in  terms  capable  of  being 
pressed  upon  Ministers  and  the  administrative  experts. 
This  identity  and  precision  can  only  be  secured  by  central 
action.  The  work  of  the  local  Trades  Councils  must,  there- 
fore, as  regards  all  Parliamentary  action,  be  executive  only. 
Both  in  order  to  retain  the  confidence  of  the  central  executive 
of  each  trade,  and  to  function  properly  as  a  part  of  the 
political  machine,  the  local  councils  would  have  rigidly  to 
confine  themselves  to  pushing  the  official  Trade  Union 
programme  for  the  time  being.  If  any  of  their  members 
wanted  this  programme  altered,  he  could  bring  his  proposal 
forward  in  the  local  branch  of  his  own  union,  have  it  voted 
upon  by  his  fellow-tradesmen,  and  get  it  sent  up  to  his  own 
central  executive.  If  it  was  not  a  matter  on  which  his  own 
Trade  Union  could  be  induced  to  take  action,  it  would  most 
assuredly  not  be  fit  for  adoption  by  a  federation  of  Trade 
Unions.  The  local  Trades  Council  would,  without  inter- 
fering with  general  policy,  find  abundant  occupation  in 
organising  and  educating  the  local  Trade  Unionist  electors  ; 
in  carrying  out  the  frequent  instructions  received  from  the 
skilled  political  staff  of  the  Parliamentary  Committee  in 
watching  and  criticising  the  action  of  the  Parliamentary 
representatives  of  the  constituency,  to  whatever  party  they 
belonged  ;  in  supplementing  and  supervising  the  local  work  of 
the  mines,  factory,  and  sanitary  inspectors  ;  and,  wherever  it 
was  thought  fit,  in  conducting  a  municipal  campaign.  For 
all  elections  to  local  bodies,  it  could,  of  course,  frame  its 
own  programme.  Here  it  would  have  to  act  as  its  own 
Representative  Assembly.  Like  the  Trade  Union  Congress 
the  Trades  Council  would  have  to  elect  and  to  trust  a 
responsible  cabinet ;  to  restrict  it  to  a  Trade  Union  as  dis- 
tinguished from  a  general  political  programme  ;  to  provide  it 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  275 

with  officers  and  funds  adequate  to  its  task  ;  to  expect  that 
it  should  act  only  after  inquiry  and  expert  or  professional 
advice ;  and  above  all,  to  insist  that  it  should  keep  itself  free 
from  suspicion  of  acting  in  the  interests  of  any  particular 
party. 

We  are  thus  brought  back,  at  each  stage  of  the  organ- 
isation, to  the  paramount  need  of  intellectual  leadership. 
Without  concerted  federal  action  between  the  trades,  no 
progress  can  be  made  in  carrying  out  their  desires  for  the 
use  of  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment.  Without  a  central 
committee  really  directing  and  concentrating  the  action  of 
the  local  councils,  no  electoral  campaign  can  ever  be  effec- 
tive. Without  a  "  Front  Bench  "  of  responsible  leaders,  no 
Representative  Assembly  can  ever  formulate  a  consistent 
programme,  or  rise  above  the  dignity  of  a  public  meeting. 
The  great  officials  of  the  leading  trades  must  realise  that  it 
is  their  duty,  not  merely  to  stir  up  their  own  branches  to 
feeble  and  fitful  agitation  for  the  particular  legal  reforms  that 
they  desire  themselves,  but  to  get  constructed  the  federal 
organisation  which  alone  can  secure  their  accomplishment. 
In  this  federal  organisation  they  must  themselves  take  the 
leading  part.  For  this  work  they  are  at  present,  with  all 
their  capacity  and  force,  usually  quite  unfit.  Each  man 
knows  his  own  trade,  and  the  desires  of  his  own  union,  but 
is  both  ignorant  and  indifferent  as  to  the  needs  or  desires  of 
every  other  trade.  Before  they  can  form  anything  like  a 
Cabinet  with  a  definite  and  consistent  policy,  they  must 
learn  how  to  frame  a  precise  and  detailed  programme  which 
shall  include  the  particular  legislative  regulations  desired  by 
each  trade,  whilst  avoiding  the  Shibboleths  of  any  political 
party.  Nor  is  this  an  impossible  dream.  At  one  period,  as  we 
have  elsewhere  described,1  the  Trade  Union  world  possessed, 
in  "  the  Junta  "  and  their  immediate  successors,  an  extremely 
efficient  Cabinet,  which  both  led  the  Trade  Union  Congress 
and  directed  the  action  of  the  Trades  Councils.  In  close 
communication  with  the  executives  of  the  great  trades,  and 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  215-283. 


276  Trade  Union  Function 

making  unstinted  use  of  expert  counsel,  this  Junta  prepared 
a  reasoned  and  practicable  programme ;  explained  it  to 
representative  gatherings  by  which  it  was  ratified ;  and 
enlisted  the  Trades  Councils  in  an  organised  electoral 
campaign  in  its  support.  The  result  was  seen  in  the 
memorable  Parliamentary  triumphs  of  1871  and  1875. 
With  the  passing  away  of  the  Junta,  and  the  breach  between 
the  Parliamentary  Committee  and  its  unpaid  counsellors, 
this  effective  leadership  came  insensibly  to  an  end.  If  the 
machinery  is  again  to  become  effective,  the  Parliamentary 
Committee  must  realise  that  its  duty  is  to  lead  both  the 
Trade  Union  Congress  and  the  Trades  Councils ;  to 
formulate  its  own  policy  ;  to  provide  itself  with  an  adequate 
salaried  staff;  and,  above  all,  to  make  the  fullest  possible 
use  of  professional  experts.  With  the  creation  of  a 
strongly  centralised,  and  thoroughly  equipped  political 
federation  confining  its  work  exclusively  to  Trade  Union 
objects,  the  organised  trades  might  reasonably  hope  to  obtain 
the  same  measure  of  success  in  the  detailed  legal  regulation 
of  the  conditions  of  their  labor,  as  that  achieved  by  such 
"  old  Parliamentary  hands "  as  the  Coalminers  and  the 
Cotton  Operatives,  whilst  these  latter  unions  would  find 
their  power  to  obtain  further  regulation  in  their  own  trades 
indefinitely  increased  by  the  effective  support  of  the  whole 
Trade  Union  world.1 

1  The  degeneration  of  the  whole  political  machinery  has,  during  the  last 
few  years,  become  so  obvious  to  the  leading  Trade  Unionists,  that  spasmodic 
attempts  at  reform  have  been  made.  We  cannot,  in  this  analytical  volume,  go 
into  the  details  of  the  story  of  how  the  Parliamentary  Committee  of  1895,  by  tne 
casting  vote  of  its  chairman,  imposed  a  brand  new  constitution  on  the  Trade 
Union  Congress.  We  need  only  remind  the  reader  that  by  the  new  Standing 
Orders,  which  were  held  to  govern  the  Cardiff  Congress  before  they  were 
adopted,  the  Parliamentary  Committee  brought  in  three  important  innovations. 
No  Trade  Unionist  could  be  elected  as  a  delegate  unless  he  was  either  a  paid 
official  of  his  own  union,  or  else  still  working  at  his  original  trade.  The  Trades 
Councils  were  excluded  from  all  representation  or  participation  in  the  Congress. 
And,  most  important  of  all,  the  method  of  voting  in  Congress  was  changed  from 
the  ordinary  practice  of  Representative  Assemblies  to  a  system  of  voting  by 
trades.  These  alterations,  it  will  be  seen,  do  not  proceed  along  the  lines  which 
we  have  suggested.  There  is  no  proposal  to  increase  the  efficiency  or  strengthen 
the  staff  of  the  Parliamentary  Committee,  or  to  co-ordinate  the  several  parts  of 


The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  277 

the  political  machine.  Instead  of  intellectual  leadership  being  provided,  we  see 
an  attempt  merely  to  silence  or  exclude  the  troublesome  elements.  We  need 
not  dwell  upon  the  first  of  the  alterations,  aimed,  as  it  was,  merely  at  one  or  two 
influential  delegates  whose  exclusion  was  desired  by  the  dominant  officials.  By 
abruptly  turning  out  the  Trades  Councils,  who  actually  initiated  the  Congress 
twenty-seven  years  before,  and  had  ever  since  taken  a  vigorous  part,  the 
Parliamentary  Committee  cut  adrift  the  very  bodies  upon  which  any  effective 
Trade  Union  campaign  in  the  constituencies  must  depend.  The  Trades  Councils, 
thus  "  outlawed  "  from  the  Trade  Union  world,  are  now  centres  of  bitter  hostility 
to  the  salaried  officials  of  the  great  trades ;  sources  of  dissension  and  political 
weakness,  instead  of  being  valuable  supports  and  allies.  But  the  most  important 
and,  as  we  think,  most  injurious  change  was  that  effected  in  the  method  of 
voting.  Prior  to  1895,  though  the  Unions  were  allowed  to  send  delegates  in 
proportion  to  their  membership  and  contribution  to  the  Congress  funds,  each 
delegate  had  an  individual  vote,  and  no  proxy  voting  was  allowed.  In  this 
way,  the  larger  unions  could,  if  they  chose  to  send  their  full  number  of  dele- 
gates, exercise  their  due  proportion  of  voting  power.  But  the  officials  of  some 
powerful  societies  found  the  arrangement  inconvenient.  In  some  cases  their 
societies  demurred  to  the  expense  of  sending  more  than  three  or  four  delegates, 
and  thus  failed  to  secure  a  proportionate  influence.  In  other  cases  when  the  full 
number  of  delegates  was  sent,  some  of  these  insisted  on  exercising  an  independent 
judgment,  and  voted  according  to  their  own  political  sympathies,  or  in  response 
to  appeals  from  the  smaller  trades.  In  the  absence  of  any  leadership  of  the 
Congress  as  a  whole,  independence  degenerated  into  anarchy.  To  the  practical 
officials  of  the  Coal  and  Cotton  industries,  the  flighty  and  irresponsible  behaviour 
of  the  Congress  appeared  likely  to  militate  against  the  success  of  the  particular 
technical  measures  promoted  by  their  own  unions.  It  does  not  seem  to  have 
occurred  to  them  that  it  might  be  their  duty  to  put  their  brains  into  the 
business  ;  to  come  forward  as  the  Cabinet  of  the  Congress,  formulating  a  con- 
sistent policy  for  the  Trade  Union  world  as  a  whole ;  and  boldly  to  appeal  for 
the  confidence  and  the  pecuniary  support  by  which  alone  any  policy  could  be 
carried  into  effect.  The  investigation  and  co-ordination  of  the  needs  of  the 
several  trades  would  have  involved,  instead  of  an  occasional  pleasant  jaunt  to 
London,  a  good  deal  of  hard  thinking,  and  many  tedious  consultations  with 
experts  of  all  kinds.  It  was  easier  to  put  themselves  in  a  position  mechanically 
to  stop  the  passing  of  any  resolution  which  seemed  likely  to  be  injurious  to  their 
trades.  The  four  representatives  of  the  coal  and  cotton  industries  on  the 
committee,  therefore,  insisted  on  the  adoption  of  the  so-called  "proxy  voting" 
used  by  the  Miners'  Federation  in  their  own  conferences.  Under  this  system 
each  trade  as  a  whole  is  accorded  the  number  of  votes  to  which  its  aggregate 
membership  entitles  it,  but  is  not  required  to  send  more  than  a  single  delegate. 
If  more  than  one  are  sent,  they  may  decide  among  themselves  how  the  vote  of 
the  trade  shall  be  cast,  and  may  even  entrust  their  voting  cards  to  one  among 
their  number,  and  leave  the  Congress.  It  is  obvious  that  this  mechanical  system 
of  voting  tends  to  throw  the  entire  power  in  the  hands  of  the  officials.  In  fact, 
already  at  the  Congress  of  1895,  one  society,  enjoying  forty-five  votes,  sent  only 
its  general  secretary  to  represent  it,  and  as  this  economical  practice  leaves  the 
voting  power  of  the  union  unimpaired,  it  will  certainly  be  adopted  by  others. 
By  this  system  the  officers  of  the  great  unions  have  secured  their  own  permanent 
re-election  on  the  Parliamentary  Committee,  and,  whenever  needed,  the  power 
to  reject  any  proposal  before  Congress,  without  incurring  either  the  "  intolerable 
toil  of  thought,"  which  due  consideration  of  the  needs  of  the  smaller  trades  would 
involve,  or  the  trouble  of  any  intellectual  leadership  of  the  Congress  as  a  whole. 


278  Trade  Union  Function 


It  will  henceforth  be  less  than  ever  necessary  for  the  officials  of  the  great  trades 
to  intervene  in  the  debates,  or  to  seek  to  guide  the  less  experienced  sections  of 
the  Trade  Union  world.  Already  at  Cardiff  signs  were  not  wanting  that  in 
future  Congresses  we  shall  see  the  big  officials,  holding  the  pack  of  voting  cards 
allotted  to  their  own  unions,  listening  contemptuously  to  the  debating  of  the 
smaller  trades,  and  silently  voting  down  any  proposition  which  displeases  them. 

But  the  new  Standing  Orders  do  more  than  destroy  the  value  of  the  Trade 
Union  Congress  as  a  deliberative  assembly,  and  deprive  it  of  its  functions  as 
a  representative  gathering  through  which  the  policy  and  programme  of  the 
Parliamentary  Committee  might  be  explained  to  the  Trade  Union  world.  The 
new  system  of  voting  contravenes,  in  the  worst  possible  way,  the  principles  of 
representation  which  we  have,  in  our  chapter  on  "  Interunion  Relations," 
deduced  from  the  nature  of  federal  association,  and  is  therefore  fraught  with 
the  gravest  danger  to  the  stability  of  the  Congress.  The  Congress,  including  as 
it  does,  many  divergent,  and  even  opposing  interests,  can  never  be  more  than  a 
loose  federation  for  the  limited  purposes  which  its  several  sections  have  really  in 
common.  Its  decisions  ought  therefore  to  be  arrived  at,  not  by  mere  majority 
vote,  but  by  consultation  between  the  sections,  with  a  view  of  discovering  the 
"greatest  common  measure."  But  under  the  present  system  the  Miners'  Federa- 
tion and  the  United  Textile  Factory  Workers'  Association  together  number  a 
third  of  the  membership  represented  at  the  Congress,  whilst  so  long  as  they  act 
in  conjunction  with  the  Amalgamated  Societies  of  Engineers  and  Carpenters,  and 
the  National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives,  they  constitute  an  absolute 
majority  of  any  possible  Congress.  To  give  to  five  trades  an  absolute  majority 
over  the  combined  forces  of  all  the  rest,  must,  if  persisted  in,  either  extinguish 
any  chance  of  energetic  political  co-operation  by  the  others,  or  else  lead  to  these 
forming  a  new  federation  of  their  own. 


CHAPTER    V 


THE    STANDARD    RATE 

.  s 

AMONG  Trade  Union  Regulations  there  is  one  which  stands 
out  as  practically  universal,  namely,  the  insistence  on  pay- 
ment according  to  some  definite  standard,  uniform  in  its 
application.  Even  so  rudimentary  a  form  of  combination  as 
the  "  shop  club  "  requires  that  all  its  members  shall  receive, 
as  a  minimum,  the  rate  agreed  upon  with  the  foreman  for 
the  particular  job.  The  organised  local  or  national  union 
carries  the  principle  further,  and  insists  on  a  Standard  Rate 
of  payment  for  all  its  members  in  the  town  or  district.  The 
Standard  Rate,  it  should  be  observed,  is  only  a  minimum, 
never  a  maximum.  The  Friendly  Society  of  Operative 
Stonemasons,  for  instance,  agrees  (1897)  with  the  London 
Central  Master  Builders'  Association  that  all  its  able-bodied 
members  shall  receive  not  less  than  tenpence  halfpenny  per 
hour.  But  the  Society  has  no  objection  to  an  employer 
offering  a  particular  stonemason,  whose  skill  or  character 
is  valued,  any  higher  rate  that  he  may  choose.  The 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Tailors,  in  conjunction  with  the 
Master  Tailors'  Association  of  the  particular  town,  settles  a 
"  log  "  fixing  the  payment  for  each  kind  of  garment.  But 
this  does  not  prevent  West  End  master  tailors,  with  the  full 
sanction  of  the  union,  paying  some  members  far  above  the 
London  log  rates.  In  fact,  though  there  are  certain  seeming 
exceptions  with  which  we  shall  deal  separately,  we  know  of 
no  case  in  which  a  Trade  Union  forbids  or  discourages  its 


280  Trade  Union  Fimction 

members  from  receiving  a  higher  rate  of  remuneration,  for 
the  work  actually  performed,  than  the  common  Standard 
Rate  fixed  for  the  whole  body. 

But  although  the  Standard  Rate  is  a  minimum,  not  a 
maximum,  the  establishment  of  this  minimum  necessarily 
results  in  a  nearer  approximation  to  equality  of  rates  than 
would  otherwise  prevail.  Trade  Union  officials  who  have  had 
to  construct  a  piecework  list,  or  to  extend  such  a  list  from  one 
shop  to  the  whole  town,  or  from  one  town  to  the  whole 
trade,  know  that,  in  order  to  secure  a  standard  list  of  prices, 
they  have  had  to  pare  down  the  rates  hitherto  enjoyed  by 
particular  shops  or  even  particular  towns.  It  is  exactly 
this  willingness  on  the  part  of  the  more  fortunately  situated 
sections  of  the  trade  to  forego,  for  the  sake  of  a  Standard 
Rate,  the  higher  rates  which  happen,  by  some  accident,  to 
have  become  current  for  a  particular  line  of  work,  that  makes 
uniformity  possible.  We  have  already  cited,  in  describing 
how  Trade  Unionism  breaks  down  local  monopoly,  the  case 
of  the  Cotton -weavers,  who  discovered  that,  in  order  to  secure 
a  uniform  list  of  piecework  prices — meaning,  to  the  majority 
of  members,  an  advance  of  wages — one  or  two  districts  had 
to  consent  to  a  positive  reduction  of  the  rates  they  had 
hitherto  enjoyed.1  The  powerful  society  of  Flint  Glass 
Makers  has  recently  afforded  us  an  even  more  striking 
example.  When  in  1895  the  Flint  Glass  Makers  concerted 
with  their  employers  a  uniform  "catalogue  of  prices"  for  all 
the  glass  works  in  Yorkshire,  the  York  branch,  which  enjoyed 
higher  rates  than  any  other  in  the  county,  at  first  vehemently 
protested.  A  uniform  list,  they  urged,  "was  impracticable, 
unless  by  some  section  of  us  making  enormous  sacrifices"; 
and  its  enforcement  would  involve  the  "edifying  spectacle  of 
a  Trade  Union  compelling  its  members  to  work  at  a  reduced 
wage,  when  neither  they  nor  the  employer  desired  it." z 
Notwithstanding  this  protest,  the  members  of  the  union 

1  See  the  chapter  on  "The  Unit  of  Government." 

z  Letter  from  T.  Mawson,  a  member  of  the  York  branch,  in  the  Flint  Glass 
Makers'  Magazine,  October  1895  ;  vol.  ii.  No.  8,  pp.  427,  428. 


The  Standard  Rate  281 

approved  the  preparation  of  the  uniform  list,  which  was 
submitted  to  general  meetings  of  all  the  Yorkshire  branches. 
The  issue  was  thus  put  before  the  York  members,  and  though 
it  was  made  clear  that  the  new  list  would  involve  a  reduction 
of  their  own  earnings,  the  feeling  in  favor  of  uniformity  was 
so  strong  that,  as  the  general  secretary  records,  out  of  a  total 
of  eighty-four  members  in  the  branch  at  the  time, "  the  vote 
against  the  catalogue  was  only  the  miserable  total  of  nine."  l 

This  conception  of  a  Standard  Rate  is,  as  we  need  hardly 
explain,  an  indispensable  requisite  of  Collective  Bargaining. 
Without  some  common  measure,  applicable  to  all  the  work- 
men concerned,  no  general  treaty  with  regard  to  wages 
would  be  possible.  But  the  use  of  a  definite  standard  of 
measurement  is  not  merely  an  adjunct  of  the  Method  of 
Collective  Bargaining.  It  is  required  for  any  wholesale 
determination  of  wages  upon  broad  principles.  The  most 
autocratic  and  unfettered  employer  spontaneously  adopts 
Standard  Rates  for  classes  of  workmen,  just  as  the  large 
shopkeeper  fixes  his  prices,  not  according  to  the  higgling 
capacity  of  particular  customers,  but  by  a  definite  percentage 
on  cost.2  This  conception  of  a  consistent  standard  of 
measurement  the  Trade  Union  seeks  to  extend  from 
establishments  to  districts,  and  from  districts  to  the  whole 
area  of  the  trade  within  the  kingdom. 

This  Trade  Unionist  insistence  on  a  Standard  Rate  has 
been  the  subject  of  bitter  denunciation.     The  payment  of  "bad 
and  lazy  workmen  as  highly  as  those  who  are  skilled  and  indus- . 
trious," 3  "  setting  a  premium  on  idleness  and    incapacity," 

1  Address  of  the  Central  Secretary  of  the  Society,  in  the  Flint  Glass  Makers' 
Magazine,  October  1895  >  vo^  "•  No.  8,  pp.  447-451. 

2  Practical  convenience  and  the  growth    of  large  establishments  have,  no 
doubt,  much  to  do  with  the  adoption  of  uniformity.     The  little  working  master, 
or  small  employer,  could  know  personally  every  workman,  and  adjust  without 
much  difficulty  a  graduated  rate  of  wages.     But  the  modern  employer  of  labor 
on  a  large  scale  cannot  be  bothered  with  precisely  graduated  special  rates  for 
each  of  his  thousand   "hands."      It  suits  him  better  to  adopt  some  common 
principle  of  payment,  simple  of  application  by  his  clerks  and  easily  comprehended 
by  the  workmen. 

Measures  for  putting  an  End  to  the  Abuses  of  Trade  Unions,  by  Frederic 
Hill  (London,  1868),  p.  3.      So  persistent  is  this  delusion  that  Mr.  Lecky,  writing 


282  Trade  Union  Function 

"destructive  to  the  legitimate  ambition  of  industry  and  merit," 
that  "  worst  kind  of  Communism,  the  equal  remuneration  of 
all  men,"  are  only  samples  of  the  abusive  rhetoric  of  capitalists 
and  philosophers  on  the  subject.  Even  as  lately  as  1871 
a  distinguished  economist  poured  out  the  following  tirade 
against  the  assumed  wickedness  of  the  Trade  Unions  in 
this  respect :  "  Not  yet,  but  in  course  of  time,  as  economic 
principles  become  popularly  understood,  we  shall  see  Trade 
Unions  purged  of  their  most  erroneous  and  mischievous 
purpose  of  seeking  an  uniform  rate  of  wages  without  regard 
to  differences  of  skill,  knowledge,  industry,  and  character. 
There  is  no  tenet  of  Socialism  more  fatal  in  its  consequences 
than  this  insidious  and  plausible  doctrine — a  doctrine  which, 
if  acted  upon  rigidly  for  any  length  of  time  by  large  classes 
of  men,  would  stop  all  progress.  Put  in  plain  language  it 
means  that  there  shall  not  be  in  the  world  any  such  thing  as 
superior  talent  or  attainment ;  that  every  art  and  handicraft 
shall  be  reduced  to  the  level  of  the  commonest,  most 
ignorant,  and  most  stupid  of  the  persons  who  belong  to  it."  1 

Such  criticisms  are  beside  the  mark.  A  very  slight 
acquaintance  with  Trade  Unionism  would  have  shown  these 
writers  that  a  uniform  Standard  Rate  in  no  way  implies 
equality  of  weekly  wages,  and  has  no  such  object.  For 
good  or  for  evil,  the  typical  British  workman  is  not  by  any 
means  a  Communist,  and  the  Trade  Union  regulations  are, 
as  we  shall  see,  quite  free  from  any  theoretic  "  yearnings  for 
equal  division  of  unequal  earnings." 

The  misapprehension  arises  from  a  confusion  between 
the  rate  of  payment  and  the  amount  actually  earned  by  the 
workman.  What  the  Trade  Union  insists  on,  as  a  necessary 
condition  of  the  very  existence  of  Collective  Bargaining,  is  a 
Standard  Rate  of  payment  for  the  work  actually  performed. 
But  this  is  consistent  with  the  widest  possible  divergence 

in  1896,  naively  echoes  the  charge  against  the  Trade  Unions  by  implying  that 
"  they  insist  on  the  worst  workman  being  paid  as  much  as  the  best." — Demo- 
cracy and  Liberty,  vol.  ii.  p.  385. 

1  Presidential  Address  of  William  Newmarch  at  Social  Science  Congress  of 
1871  (Transactions  of  Social  Science  Association,  1871,  p.  117). 


The  Standard  Rate  283 

between  the  actual  weekly  incomes  of  different  workmen. 
Thus  we  have  the  significant  fact  that  the  Standard  Rate 
insisted  on  by  the  great  majority  of  Trade  Unionists  is,  not 
any  definite  sum  per  hour,  but  a  list  of  piecework  prices. 
The  extent  to  which  these  piecework  lists  prevail  throughout 
the  country  is  seldom  realised.  Even  those  who  have  heard 
of  the  elaborate  tonnage  rates  of  the  Ironworkers,  Steel- 
smelters,  and  Coalminers,  and  the  complicated  cotton  lists, 
which  together  govern  the  remuneration  of  a  fourth  of  the 
Trade  Union  world,  often  forget  the  innumerable  other 
trades,  in  which  (as  with  the  Tailors,  Bootmakers,  Com- 
positors, Coopers,  Basketmakers,  Brushmakers)  lists  of  prices, 
signed  by  employers  and  employed,  and  revised  from  time  to 
time,  date  from  the  very  beginning  of  the  century.1  When, 
as  in  all  these  cases,  the  Standard  Rate  takes  the  form  of  a 
schedule  of  piecework  prices,  it  is  clear  that  there  can  be  no 
question  of  equalising  the  actual  earnings  of  different  work- 
men. One  basketmaker  or  one  coalminer  may  be  earning 
two  pounds  a  week,  whilst  another,  receiving  the  same 
Standard  Rate  and  working  the  same  number  of  hours, 
may  get  less  than  thirty  shillings  ;  and  another,  putting  in 
only  half-time,  may  have  only  ten  or  fifteen  shillings  for  his 
week's  income. 

Nor  can  it  be  assumed  that  in  the  industries  in  which 
the  Trade  Union  rate  is  not  based  on  piecework,  but  takes  the 
form  of  a  definite  standard  wage  per  hour,  this  necessarily 
implies  equality  of  remuneration.  Even  where  workmen  in 
such  trades  put  in  the  same  number  of  hours,  their  weekly 
incomes  will  often  be  found  to  differ  very  materially.  Thus, 
whilst  ordinary  plumbing,  bricklaying,  and  masonry  is  paid 
for  at  uniform  rates  per  hour,  directly  the  job  involves  any 
special  skill,  the  employer  finds  it  advantageous  to  pay  a 
higher  rate,  and  the  Trade  Union  cordially  encourages  this 
practice.  The  superior  bricklayer,  for  instance,  is  seldom 

1  These  piecework  lists  can  now  be  conveniently  studied  in  the  admirable 
selection  published  by  the  Labor  Department  of  the  Board  of  Trade  as  Part  II. 
of  the  Report  on  Wages  and  Hours  of  Labor,  1894  [C,  7567,-!]. 


Trade  Union  Function 

employed  at  the  Standard  Rate,  but  is  always  getting  jobs 
at  brick-cutting  (or  "  gauge  work  "),  furnace-building,  or  sewer 
construction,  paid  for  at  rates  from  ten  to  fifty  per  cent 
over  the  standard  wage.  In  all  industries  we  find  firms  with 
"special  reputations  for  a  high  class  of  production  habitually 
paying,  with  full  Trade  Union  approval,  more  than  the 
Trade  Union  rate,  in  order  to  attract  to  their  establishment 
the  most  skilful  and  best  conducted  workmen.  In  other 
cases,  where  the  employer  rigidly  adheres  to  the  common 
rate,  the  superior  workman  finds  his  advantage,  if  not 
actually  in  higher  money  earnings,  in  more  agreeable 
conditions  of  employment.  In  a  large  building  the 
employer  will  select  his  best  stonemasons  to  do  the  carving, 
an  occupation  not  involving  great  exertion  and  consistent 
with  an  occasional  pipe,  whilst  the  common  run  of  workmen 
will  be  setting  stones  under  the  foreman's  eye.  The  best 
carpenters,  when  not  earning  extra  rates  for  "  staircasing " 
or  "  handrailing,"  will  get  the  fine  work  which  combines 
variety  and  lightness,  and  is  done  in  the  workshop,  leaving 
to  the  rougher  hands  the  laying  down  of  flooring  and  other 
heavy  mechanical  tasks.  These  distinctions  may  seem 
trivial  to  the  professional  or  business  man,  who  to  a  large 
extent  controls  the  conditions  under  which  he  works.  But 
no  workman  fails  to  appreciate  the  radical  difference  in 
net  advantageousness  between  two  different  jobs,  one  in- 
volving exposure  to  the  weather,  wear  and  tear  of  clothing, 
monotonous  muscular  exertion,  and  incessant  supervision, 
and  the  other  admitting  a  considerable  share  of  personal 
liberty,  agreeably  diversified  in  character,  and  affording  scope 
for  initiative  and  address.  Though  there  may  be  in  such 
cases  equality  in  the  number  of  shillings  received  at  the  end 
of  the  week,  the  remuneration  for  the  efforts  and  sacrifices 
actually  made  will  have  been  at  very  different  rates  in  the 
two  cases. 

We  do  not  wish  to  obscure  the  fact  that  a  Standard 
Rate  on  a  timework  basis  does,  in  practice,  result  in  a  nearer 
approach  to  uniformity  of  money  earnings  than  a  Standard 


The  Standard  Rate  289 

If  he  were  paid  by  the  hour  or  the  day,  he  would  need,  in 
order  to  maintain  the  same  rate  of  remuneration  for  the 
work  done,  to  discover  each  day  precisely  to  what  degree 
the  machinery  was  being  "  speeded  up,"  and  to  be  perpetually 
making  demands  for  an  increase  in  his  time  wages.  Such 
an  arrangement  could  not  fail  to  result  in  the  employer 
increasing  the  work  faster  than  the  pay. 

Under  a  system  of  payment  by  the  amount  of  yarn  spun, 
the  operative  automatically  gets  the  benefit  of  any  increase  in 
the  number  of  spindles  or  rate  of  speed.  An  exact  uniformity 
of  the  rate  of  remuneration  is  maintained  between  man  and 
man,  and  between  mill  and  mill.  If  any  improvement  takes 
place  in  the  process,  by  which  the  operative's  labor  is 
reduced,  the  onus  of  procuring  a  change  in  the  rate  of  pay 
falls  on  the  employer.  The  result  is,  that  so  effectually  is 
the  cotton-spinner  secured  by  his  piecework  lists  against 
being  compelled  to  give  more  work  without  more  pay,  that 
it  has  been  found  desirable  deliberately  to  concede  to  the 
employers,  by  lowering  the  rates  as  the  number  of  spindles 
increases,  some  share  of  the  resulting  advantages,  in  order 
that  the  Trade  Union  may  encourage  enterprising  mill-owners 
in  the  career  of  improvement.  The  cotton-weavers  have  a 
similar  experience.  The  weaver's  labor  depends  upon  the 
character  of  the  cloth  to  be  woven,  involving  a  complicated 
calculation  of  the  number  of  "  picks,"  etc.  Time  wages 
would  leave  them  practically  at  the  employers'  mercy  for  all 
but  the  very  easiest  work.  But  by  a  highly  technical  and 
complex  list  of  piecework  rates,  every  element  by  which  the 
labor  is  increased  effects  an  exactly  corresponding  variation 
in  the  remuneration.  Only  under  such  a  system  could  any 
uniformity  of  rate  be  secured. 

In  another  great  class  of  cases  piecework  is  preferred  by 

machine,  i.e.  mental  strain.  Those  who  have  observed  the  mulespinner  in 
Oldham  in  the  midst  of  the  whirling  of  2500  spindles,  or  the  female  worker  in 
Burnley  environed  by  four  or  six  shuttles,  working  at  the  speed  of  200  picks  per 
minute,  know  what  a  higher  degree  of  mental  application  is  here  demanded." — 
The  Cotton  Trade  in  England  and  on  the  Continent  t  by  Dr.  G.  von  Schulze- 
Gaevernitz  (London,  1895),  pp.  126,  127. 

VOL.  I  U 


290  Trade  Union  Function 

the  workmen,  with  the  same  object  of  securing  a  Standard 
Rate,  but  under  entirely  different  conditions.  The  coal- 
miners  have,  in  some  counties,  had  a  long  experience  of 
both  time  wages  and  piecework,  with  the  result  that,  where- 
ever  there  is  a  strong  Trade  Union,  piecework  is  insisted  on  for 
all  hewers.  The  explanation  is  to  be  found  in  the  circum- 
stances under  which  the  work  is  done.  Employers  have 
found  it  impossible  to  supervise  by  foremen  or  managers  the 
numerous  hewers  scattered  in  the  recesses  of  the  mine.  The 
only  possible  alternative  to  paying  the  hewers  at  piecework 
rates,  was  to  let  out  the  different  parts  of  the  mine  to 
working  contractors,  who  engaged  hewers  by  the  hour  to 
work  alongside  them.  This  was  the  notorious  "  Butty 
System,"  against  which  the  organised  hewers  have  persistently 
struggled.  It  was  found  that,  whatever  was  the  customary 
standard  of  daily  time  wages,  the  "  Butty  Master,"  who  set 
the  pace,  was  always  increasing  the  quantity  of  work  to  be 
done  for  those  wages  by  himself  putting  in  ah  unusual 
intensity  of  effort.  It  is  obvious  that,  under  this  system,  the 
ordinary  hewer  lost  all  security  of  a  Standard  Rate.  It  paid 
the  Butty  Master  to  be  always  "  speeding  up,"  because  he 
received  the  product,  not  of  his  own  extra  exertion  alone, 
but  of  that  of  all  his  gang.  The  only  method  by  which  the 
ordinary  hewers  could  secure  identity  of  rate  was  to  dispense 
with  the  Butty  Masters,  and  themselves  work  by  the  piece. 

We  shall  find  exactly  the  same  preference  for  piecework 
wages  in  other  trades  among  men  who  work  under  a  sub- 
contractor, or  in  subordination  to  another  class  of  workmen 
paid  by  the  piece.  The  strikers,  for  instance,  who  work  with 
smiths  paid  by  the  piece,  were  themselves  formerly  paid  time 
wages.  In  most  parts  of  the  country  they  have  now  been 
successful  in  obtaining  the  boon  of  a  piecework  rate  pro- 
portionate to  that  of  the  smiths,  so  that  they  are  secured 
extra  remuneration  for  any  extra  spurt  put  on  by  the  smith. 
Another  large  class  of  workmen  in  a  somewhat  similar 
position  have  not  been  so  fortunate.  The  shipyard  "  helpers,' 
who  work  under  the  platers  (iron-shipbuilders),  are  paid  b} 


The  Standard  Rate  291 

the  day,  whilst  the  platers  receive  piecework  rates.  The 
first  object  of  any  combination  of  helpers  has  always  been 
to  secure  piecework  rates,  in  order  that  their  remuneration 
might  bear  some  proportion  to  the  rapidity  and  intensity  of 
work,  the  pace  being  set  by  the  platers.  But  owing  to  the 
strength  of  the  Boilermakers'  Union,  to  which  the  platers 
belong,  the  helpers  have  never  been  able  to  attain  their 
object.1  The  iron  and  steel  industries  afford  numerous  other 
instances  in  which  workers  paid  by  the  day  are  in  sub- 
ordination to  workers  paid  by  the  piece.  In  all  these  cases, 
the  subordinate  workers  desire  to  be  paid  by  the  piece,  in 
order  that  they  may  secure  a  greater  uniformity  in  the  rate 
of  payment  for  the  work  actually  done. 

Coming  now  to  the  trades  in  which  piecework  is  most 
strongly  objected  to  by  the  operatives,  we  shall  find  the 
argument  again  turning  upon  the  question  of  uniformity  of 
the  rate  of  remuneration.  The  engineers  have  always  protested 
that  the  introduction  of  piecework  into  their  trade  almost 
necessarily  implied  a  reversion  to  Individual  Bargaining.  The 
work  of  a  skilled  mechanic  in  an  engineering  shop  differs 
from  job  to  job  in  such  a  way  as  to  make,  under  a  piece- 
work system,  a  new  contract  necessary  for  each  job.  Each 
man,  too,  will  be  employed  at  an  operation  differing,  if  only 
in  slight  degree,  from  those  of  his  fellows.  If  they  are  all 
working  by  the  hour,  a  collective  bargain  can  easily  be  made 
and  adhered  to.  But  where  each  successive  job  differs  from 
the  last,  if  only  in  small  details,  it  is  impossible  to  work  out. 
in  advance  any  list  of  prices  to  which  all  the  men  can  agree 
to  adhere.  The  settlement  for  each  job  must  necessarily  be 
left  to  be  made  between  the  foreman  and  the  workman 
concerned.  Collective  Bargaining  becomes,  therefore,  im- 
possible. But  this  is  not  all.  The  uncertainty  as  to  the 

1  See,  for  the  Boilermakers'  or  Platers'  Helpers,  the  paper  by  J.  Lynch,  in 
the  Report  of  the  Industrial  Remuneration  Conference  (London,  1885),  and  the 
discussion  at  the  Trade  Union  Congress  of  1878.  Many  of  the  helpers  are  now 
members  of  the  National  Amalgamated  Union  of  Labor  and  other  laborers' 
unions  ;  see  the  evidence  given  on  their  behalf  before  the  Royal  Commission  on 
Labor,  I7th  May  1892,  Group  A. 


292  Trade  Union  Function 

time  and  labor  which  a  particular  job  will  involve  makes 
it  impossible  for  the  foreman,  with  the  best  intentions  in  the 
world,  to  fix  the  prices  of  successive  jobs  so  that  the  workman 
will  obtain  the  same  earnings  for  the  same  effort.  And 
when  we  remember  the  disadvantage  at  which,  unprotected 
by  collective  action,  the  individual  operative  necessarily 
stands  in  bargaining  with  the  capitalist  employer,  we  shall 
easily  understand  how  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers 
should  have  been  led  to  declare  that,  under  this  system  of 
settling  a  special  price  for  each  job,  "  it  is  well  known  that 
piecework  is  not  a  bargain,  but  a  price  dictated  by  the 
employer  and  lowered  at  will."  And  the  report  adds  that 
"  the  system  has  often  been  made  the  instrument  of  large 
reductions  of  wages,  which  have  ended  in  the  deterioration  of 
the  conditions  of  the  workmen.  ...  If  an  expert  workman, 
by  his  skill  and  industry,  earns  more  than  his  neighbour,  and 
much  more  than  his  daily  wages  come  to,  a  reduction  is  at 
once  made,  and  made  again  until  eventually  the  most  expert 
is  only  able,  by  intense  application  and  industry,  to  earn  a 
bare  living,  whilst  the  less  skilful  is  reduced  below  living 
prices." l 

We  could  cite  from  the  reports  of  the  great  national 
unions  of  the  Engineers,  Ironfounders,  and  Carpenters  innu- 
merable similar  protests  against  piecework  in  their  trades, 
all  based  upon  the  proved  impossibility  of  maintaining  a 
Standard  Rate,  if  each  job  has  to  be  separately  priced.  It 

1  Abstract  Report  of  the  Council's  (of  the  A.  S.  E.)  Proceedings,  September 
1860  to  April  1862,  pp.  24-26. 

This  process  of  fixing  a  piecework  rate  for  all  the  men,  by  the  speed  of  an 
exceptionally  expert  workman  under  special  pressure,  has  been  more  than  once 
unconsciously  revealed  by  employers.  Already  in  1727,  in  a  manual  entitled 
The  Duty  of  a  Steward  to  his  Lord,  by  Edward  Laurence,  naive  directions  are 
given  how  to  achieve  this  object.  ' '  Also  if  any  new  sort  of  work  is  to  be  done, 
not  mentioned  in  the  following  particulars,  the  Steward's  best  way  is  to  hire  a 
good  labourer  and  to  stand  by  him  the  whole  day  to  see  that  he  does  a  good  day's 
work,  and  then  to  measure  the  same,  in  order  to  know  what  it  is  worth."  The 
efficacy  of  piecework,  as  an  expedient  for  reducing  wages  was  described  in  a  letter 
to  the  Times  in  1852  by  Charles  Walker  and  Sons,  an  engineering  firm.  "  When 
work  which  has  been  done  daywork  is  put  on  the  piece,  the  employer  usually 
regulates  the  piecework  price  a  little  tinder  the  price  of  it  at  day-work,  knowing 


The  Standard  Rate  293 

is,  however,  more  interesting  to  watch  the  same  conviction 
being  gradually  borne  in  upon  the  mind  of  an  exceptionally 
able  employer.  In  1876,  William  Denny,  the  well-known 
Clyde  shipbuilder,  who  had  put  his  whole  establishment  on 
piecework  rates,  delivered  a  remarkable  lecture  on  the 
advantages  of  this  method  of  remuneration,  alike  to  the 
employer  and  to  the  workmen,  specially  commending  the 
intensity  of  competition  which  it  secured.  He  was  utterly 
unable  to  understand  why  the  workmen  objected  to  a  system 
which,  in  giving  an  "increase  of  from  25  to  50  per  cent  in 
his  wages — and  this  increase  my  experience  confirms  as  a 
rule — puts  at  once  within  his  power  a  more  comfortable  and 
easy  style  of  living,  combined  with  an  opportunity  of  saving, 
which,  if  he  is  a  sober  and  careful  man,  will  enable  him  to 
enjoy  a  pleasant  old  age,  and  even  to  lay  by  sufficient  money 
to  enable  him  to  refuse  on  his  own  account  any  rate  of 
payment  which  he  deems  insufficient."  l 

Notwithstanding  all  these  allurements,  the  Trade 
Unions  persisted  in  their  objection.  After  ten  years'  further 
experience  of  the  working  of  piecework,  William  Denny  at 
last  perceived  the  real  root  of  the  men's  protest.  In  an 
interesting  letter  written  in  1886  he  describes  his  own 
conversion  : — 

At  the  time  I  published  my  pamphlet  The  Worth  of  Wages,  I  was 
under  the  impression  piecework  rates  would  regulate  themselves  as  I 
then  assumed  time  wages  did.  A  larger  experience  of  piecework  has 
convinced  me  that,  excepting  in  cases  where  rates  can  be  fixed  and  made 

how  production  is  increased  by  it.  But  he  finds  that  men  do  work  in  quantity 
far  beyond  what  they  have  been  doing  daywork,  earning  often  los.  per  day,  when 
at  daywork  they  had  done  much  less  than  half  the  work  at  55.  6d.  per  day.  So 
much,  indeed,  is  this  the  case,  that  manufacturers  have  made  it  a  private  rule  that 
men  for  their  extra  work  should  earn  'time  and  quarter'  or  'time  and  third,' 
and  have  reduced  the  price  accordingly  ;  that  is,  where  55.  was  the  man's  day  pay, 
the  price  should  be  so  arranged  that  ultimately  he  should  earn  6s.  3d.  or  6s.  8d. 
per  day.  This  method  we  do  not  quite  agree  with,  and  we  believe  it  has  made 
men  complain"  (Times,  Qth  January  1852).  Thus  the  employer  not  only  gets 
the  advantage  of  an  increased  output  upon  the  same  fixed  capital,  but  actually 
contrives  also  insidiously  to  alter,  to  his  own  profit,  the  proportion  between  the 
muscular  energy  expended  by  the  workman  and  the  amount  of  food  which  the 
latter  obtains. 

1  The  Worth  of  Wages,  by  William  Denny  (Dumbarton,  1876). 


294  Trade  Union  Function 

a  matter  of  agreement  between  the  whole  body  of  the  men  in  any  works 
and  their  employers,  piecework  prices  have  not  a  self-regulating  power, 
and  are  liable,  under  the  pressure  of  heavy  competition,  to  be  depressed 
below  what  I  would  consider  a  proper  level.  You  must  understand 
there  is  a  broad  and  very  real  distinction  in  piecework  between  the  kind 
of  work  which  can  be  priced  in  regular  rates  and  that  in  which  contracts 
are  taken  by  the  men  for  lump  jobs  of  greater  or  less  extent.  In  the 
former  kind  of  piecework  it  is  easily  possible  for  the  rates  to  be  effectively 
controlled  by  the  joint  efforts  of  the  employers  and  the  workpeople,  as 
it  is  in  the  case  of  time  wages.  In  the  latter,  owing  to  there  being  no 
definite  standard,  it  is  quite  possible  that  the  prices  may  be  raised  too 
high  for  competitive  efficiency,  or  depressed  to  too  low  a  point  to  recoup 
the  workmen  for  the  extra  exertion  and  initiative  induced  by  the  very 
nature  of  piecework.  In  such  work  as  that  of  rivetters,  iron  fitters,  and 
platers  and  in  much  of  carpenters'  work  standards  of  price  or  rates  can 
be  arranged  or  controlled,  and  the  workers  are  not  likely  to  endure  any 
arrangement  they  may  consider  inequitable.  They  are  indeed  much 
more  likely  by  insisting  on  uniform  rates  for  a  whole  district  to  do 
injustice  to  the  more  intelligent  and  energetic  employers,  who,  by 
introducing  new  machinery  and  new  processes,  are  directly  influential 
in  drawing  work  to  their  districts.  It  is  evident  that  if  piecework  rates 
are  not  reduced  so  as  to  make  the  improvements  in  machinery  and 
methods  introduced  by  such  employers  fully  effective  in  diminishing  cost 
of  production,  there  will  be  a  tendency  on  their  part  to  abandon  these 
attempts,  with  diminished  chances  of  work  for  their  districts.  In  the 
case  of  such  improvements  it  is  possible  to  reduce  rates  without  in  any 
way  reducing  the  effective  earnings  of  the  work-people.  I  may  say  that 
in  our  own  experience  we  have  almost  invariably  found  our  workers 
quite  willing  to  consider  these  points  fairly  and  intelligently.  Frequently 
they  themselves  make  such  suggestions  as  materially  help  us  to  reduce 
cost  of  production.  Such  cases  of  invention  and  helpfulness  on  their 
part  are  rewarded  directly  through  our  awards  scheme  of  which  you  have 
particulars. 

In  the  second  kind  of  piecework,  involving  contracts  which  cannot 
be  arranged  by  rates  and  controlled  by  the  whole  body  of  the  workers, 
the  prices  are  necessarily  a  matter  of  settlement  between  individual 
workmen  and  small  groups  of  workmen  and  their  foreman.  Here  it 
depends  upon  the  control  exercised  by  the  heads  of  the  business  whether 
this  kind  of  piecework  drifts  into  extravagances,  or  into  such  reductions 
of  contract  prices  as  either  to  reduce  them  to  less  than  the  value  of  time 
wages  or  to  so  little  above  time  wages  that  they  do  not  compensate  the 
men  for  their  extra  exertions.  We  have  found  in  testing  such  piecework 
that  the  best  method  is  to  compare  the  earnings  made  by  these  piece- 
workers in  a  given  period  with  the  time  wages  which  they  would  have 
received  for  the  same  period  ;  and  it  is  the  duty  of  one  of  our  partners 
to  control  this  section  of  the  work,  and  he  does  it  almost  invariably  to 


The  Standard  Rate  295 

the  advantage  of  the  men.  Our  idea  is  that  the  men  should  be  able  to 
average  from  25  to  50  per  cent  more  wages  on  such  piecework  within 
a  given  time  than  their  time  wages  would  amount  to.  There  are 
occasional  and  exceptional  cases  where  the  results  are  less  or  more 
favourable.  Where  they  are  less  favourable,  we  consider  them  to  be 
not  only  a  loss  to  the  men,  but  disadvantageous  to  ourselves  ;  and  our 
reason  for  this  is  very  clear,  as  unless  the  men  feel  that  their  exertions 
produce  really  better  wages,  and  that  increased  exertions  and  better 
arrangements  of  work  will  produce  still  further  increases  of  wages,  there 
is  an  end  to  all  stimulus  to  activity  or  improvement. 

I  know  an  instance  in  which  a  well-meaning  foreman,  desirous  of 
diminishing  the  cost  of  the  work  in  his  department,  reduced  his  piece- 
work prices  to  such  a  point  that  he  not  only  removed  all  healthy  stimulus 
to  activity  from  his  workmen,  but  produced  among  them  serious  discon- 
tent. Our  method  of  piecework  analysis  and  control  enabled  us  to 
discover  and  remedy  this  before  serious  disaffection  had  been  produced. 
I  know  another  instance  in  which  a  foreman,  while  avoiding  the  mistake 
I  have  just  mentioned,  gave  out  his  contracts  in  such  small  and  scattered 
portions,  and  under  such  conditions  as  to  the  way  in  which  the  work 
was  to  be  done  and  as  to  the  composition  of  the  co-partneries  formed 
by  the  men,  that  he  not  only  reduced  their  earnings  to  very  nearly  time 
rates,  but  created  very  serious  disaffection  among  them.  He  was  in  the 
habit  of  forcing  the  men  to  take  into  their  co-partneries  personal 
favourites  of  his  own,  who  very  naturally  became  burdens  upon  those 
co-partneries.  As  soon  as  our  returns  and  inquiries  revealed  to  us  these 
facts,  we  insisted  that  the  contracts  entered  into  with  the  men  should  be 
of  a  sufficient  money  amount  to  enable  them  to  organise  themselves  and 
their  work  efficiently.  We  removed  the  defective  arrangements  above 
referred  to,  and  laid  down  the  principle  that  their  co-partneries  were  to 
be  purely  voluntary.  We  were  enabled  by  these  means,  and  without 
altering  a  single  price,  to  at  once  raise  their  earnings  from  a  level  a  little 
above  what  they  could  have  made  on  time  wages  to  a  very  satisfactory 
percentage  of  increase  and  to  remove  all  discontent.  These  two  in- 
stances will  show  you  how  necessary  it  is  in  this  kind  of  piecework  that 
there  should  be  a  direct  control  over  those  who  are  carrying  it  out. 
When  the  heads  of  a  business  are  absentees  or  indifferent  the  most 
effective  way  in  which  the  workmen  can  control  such  piecework  would 
be  by  taking  care  that  the  standard  of  time  wages  was  always  kept 
perfectly  clear  and  effective,  and  that  regular  comparisons  per  hour  on 
piecework  were  made.  Such  comparisons  would  immediately  enable 
them  to  arrive  at  a  correct  conclusion  as  to  whether  the  prices  paid  them 
were  sufficiently  profitable. 

There  is  besides  a  mixed  kind  of  piecework  in  which  skilled  work- 
men employ  laborers  at  time  wages  to  do  the  unskilled  portion  of  their 
work  for  them,  Here,  too,  some  kind  of  control  is  required,  as  instances 
occasionally  occur  in  which  the  skilled  workmen  treat  their  laborers, 


296  Trade  Union  Function 

either  intentionally  or  unintentionally,  with  harshness.  I  have  even 
known  an  instance  in  which  such  piecework  contractors  reduced  their 
laborers'  time  wages  on  the  pay  day  without  having  given  them  any 
previous  notice.  On  the  other  hand,  there  are  instances  in  which  these 
laborers  behaved  in  an  unreasonable  and  unfair  spirit  to  the  skilled  work- 
men who  employ  them. 

In  conclusion,  I  would  say  that  the  method  of  piecework  is  one 
which  cannot  be  approved  or  condemned  absolutely,  but  is  dependent 
upon  the  spirit  and  the  way  in  which  it  is  carried  out  for  the  verdict 
which  should  be  passed  upon  it.  It  is  imperative  in  such  kinds  of 
piecework  as  by  their  nature  cannot  be  reduced  to  regular  rates  that 
either  the  employer  should  take  the  responsibility  of  safeguarding  his 
workmen's  interests,  or  that  the  workmen  themselves  should,  by  such  a 
method  as  I  have  suggested,  obtain  an  effective  control  over  them. 

There  are  besides  conditions  in  which  even  piecework  rates  of  a 
general  nature  may  become  instruments  of  very  great  hardship.  I  mean 
instances  in  which  the  workers  are  incapable  of  effective  resistance,  and 
in  which  employers  are  either  themselves  ground  down  under  the  force 
of  a  competition  with  which  they  are  unable  to  cope,  or  in  which,  while 
the  employers  possess  extreme  powers  of  position  and  capital,  they  are 
deficient  in  any  corresponding  sense  of  responsibility  to  their  workpeople. 
I  hope  the  day  is  not  far  distant  in  which  an  absentee  employer  would 
be  looked  upon  with  as  much  contempt  and  disapproval  as  are  absentee 
landlords.  If  such  a  healthy  public  opinion  should  ever  become  domi- 
nant, it  is  to  be  hoped  it  will  be  most  active  in  influencing  those  employers 
whose  works  are  conducted  in  great  part  or  wholly  upon  the  piecework 
method.1 

We  have,  in  this  able  explanation,  a  frank  admission  of 
the  whole  case  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers 
against  the  introduction  of  piecework  into  their  trade.  No 
Trade  Unionist  could  have  expressed  more  forcibly  than 
Denny  has  done  the  impossibility  of  a  uniform  rate  under 
a  system  of  individual  piecework  bargains.  It  is  true  that 
Denny  trusted  to  the  personal  intervention  of  an  enlightened 
and  benevolent  employer  to  mitigate  the  evil.  But  we  need 
not  wonder  that  the  workmen  have  hesitated  to  admit  a 
system  which  avowedly  involves  the  complete  surrender  of 
their  position.  Moreover,  it  is  at  least  doubtful  whether  the 
good  employer,  who  protected  his  workmen  against  his  own 

1  Life  of  William  Denny,  by  A.  B.  Bruce  (London,  1889),  p.  113  ;  see  the 
article  on  Denny  (who  lived  from  1847  to  1887)  in  the  Dictionary  of  Political 
Economy. 


The  Standard  Rate  297 

foreman's  zeal  to  lower  the  expense  of  production,  would  long 
survive  in  competition  with  his  less  scrupulous  rivals,  who 
drove  the  sharpest  possible  bargain  with  their  hands. 

It  is  interesting  to  observe  that  the  hint  thrown  out  by 
William  Denny,  as  to  the  importance  of  workmen  systemati- 
cally checking  all  the  piecework  earnings  by  the  standard 
time  rate,  has  since  been  followed  up  by  the  Amalgamated 
Society  of  Engineers.  In  some  cases,  piecework  is  now 
recognised  by  the  union,  even  in  highly  organised  districts, 
on  the  understanding  that  every  man  in  the  shop  shall  draw 
every  week  time  and  a  quarter  wages,  ivhatever  his  production 
has  been.  If  at  the  end  of  a  job  there  is  a  balance  due  to 
him,  he  is  allowed  to  receive  it.  Now,  it  is  obvious  that 
under  this  arrangement  it  is  possible  to  maintain  something 
like  a  uniform  rate.  The  natural  tendency  of  the  foreman 
to  reduce  the  rates  is  checked  by  his  knowledge,  first,  that  in 
no  case  will  it  profit  him  to  make  the  piecework  price  work 
out  at  less  than  time  and  a  quarter,  even  for  the  slowest  men 
in  the  shop  ;  and  secondly,  that,  unless  the  piecework  prices 
work  out  sufficiently  above  that  minimum  to  furnish  a  real 
incentive  for  extra  exertion,  the  operatives,  secure  in  any 
event  of  time  and  a  quarter  wages,  would  quietly  drop  back 
to  time-work  speed.  Such  a  method  of  remuneration  can- 
not, however,  be  classed  as  piecework  proper.  It  is  rather  a 
high  scale  of  time  wages,  with  a  bonus  on  extra  output.1 

The  considerations  which  converted  William  Denny 
from  his  enthusiasm  for  competitive  piecework  apply,  not 
only  to  the  various  departments  of  the  engineering  and  ship- 
building trades,  but  also  to  the  work  of  carpenters,  plumbers, 
stonemasons,  and  bricklayers.  In  all  these  trades  there  is  so 
much  difference  between  job  and  job  that  piecework  is 
inconsistent  with  Collective  Bargaining.  The  work  of  the 
plumber  engaged  to  lay  pipes,  of  varying  sizes,  in  all  kinds 
of  situations,  can  obviously  be  estimated  only  by  the  time 

1  For  other  varieties  of  "bonus  on  output,"  see  the  acute  discriminations  of 
Mr.  D.  F.  Schloss  in  The  Methods  of  Industrial  Remuneration,  2nd  ed.  (London, 
1894). 


298  Trade  Union  Function 

employed.  The  masons,  chiselling  stones  of  varied  hardness, 
different  shapes,  and  more  or  less  free  from  troublesome 
flaws,  could  not  possibly  frame  a  list  of  piecework  rates 
which  would  yield  identical  wage  to  identical  effort.  The 
same  is  true  of  the  multifarious  work  of  the  carpenter  and 
joiner.  When  we  come  to  the  actual  erection  of  houses,  in 
brick  or  stone,  it  may,  at  first  sight,  seem  as  if  uniformity 
was  more  possible.  But  if  we  watch  the  line  of  bricklayers 
or  stonemasons  working  side  by  side  at  building  a  wall,  or 
putting  up  the  carcase  of  a  house,  we  shall  see  that  it  would 
be  impossible  precisely  to  reckon  up  the  work  accomplished 
by  any  individual  among  them.  Nor  has  this  ever  been 
attempted  by  the  most  exacting  employer.  "  Piecework,"  in 
putting  up  walls  or  houses,  has,  indeed,  been  the  subject  of 
long  and  bitter  controversy  among  the  bricklayers.  But 
piecework  in  this  trade  has  always  meant,  not  the  payment 
of  each  individual  workman  by  the  piece,  but  the  letting  out 
of  a  sub-contract  for  the  whole  job  to  a  "  piecemaster,"  who 
gets  it  done  by  bricklayers  at  time  wages.  This  system  of 
sub-contract,  mistermed  "  piecework "  to  the  confusion  of 
outsiders,  is  objected  to  for  the  same  reason  as  the  coal- 
miners  allege  against  the  "  Butty  System."  The  working 
sub-contractor  forces  the  pace  in  order  to  gain  the  advantage, 
not  of  his  own  extra  exertion  alone,  but  also  that  of  his 
gang.  It  is,  in  fact,  a  fraudulent  attempt  to  obtain  piece- 
work exertion  whilst  paying  only  time  wages.  And  as  the 
system,  in  the  opinion  of  the  experts,  almost  inevitably  tends 
to  the  "  scamping  "  of  the  work  by  the  sub-contractor  or  piece- 
master,  it  has  long  since  been  given  up  by  respectable  builders, 
and  is  now  usually  prohibited  in  architects'  specifications. 

In  marked  contrast  with  the  Trade  Unions,  such  as  the 
Cotton  Operatives  and  Coalminers,  which  insist  on  piece- 
work, and  with  those,  such  as  the  Bricklayers  and  Stone- 
masons, which  insist  on  timework,  stand  those  societies  which 
accept  with  seeming  indifference  either  method  of  remunera- 
tion. The  various  Trade  Unions  of  the  compositors,  in  all 
parts  of  the  country,  have,  for  over  a  century,  formally 


The  Standard  Rate  299 

recognised  both  the  "  scale "  of  piecework  rates  and  the 
"  stab "  or  time  wages.  In  the  numerous  revisions  of  the 
collective  agreements  between  employers  and  employed,  the 
compositors  have  constantly  striven  to  maintain  a  standard 
rate.  "  Speaking  generally,"  reports  the  Revision  Sub- 
Committee  to  the  London  Society  of  Compositors  in  1890, 
"  our  desire  has  been  to  so  amend  the  scale  as  to  place  all 

>mpositors  as  far  as  possible  on  an  equality,  no  matter  what 
;lass  of  work  they  may  be  engaged  upon,  or  whether  employed 
is  piece  or  'stab  hands — allowance,  of  course,  being  made  for 

le  varying  capabilities  of  those  employed."  l     Although  the 

rork  of  a  compositor  includes  many  different  varieties,  these, 
unlike  certain  engineering  operations,  are  all  capable  of  fairly 
>recise  enumeration  in  a  "  scale"  extending  to  between  30  and 
40  pages  octavo.  Thus,  piecework  is  in  no  way  inconsistent 
with  Collective  Bargaining,  or  the  maintenance  of  a  Standard 
Rate,  and  is  therefore  not  objected  to.  On  the  other  hand, 
the  compositor  is  not  liable  to  be  "  speeded  up,"  nor  yet  over- 
Iriven  by  machinery  or  a  zealous  foreman,  so  that  there  is  no 
ison  to  object  to  time  wages,  if  the  employer  prefers  this 

'•stem.2     As  a  matter  of  fact  most  straightforward  setting-up 

1  Report  of  Sub- Committee  appointed  to  revise  the  London  Scale  of  Prices, 
[890. 

2  The  system  of  payment  by  the  piece  was  apparently  universal  in  British 
printing  offices  in  the  eighteenth  century.     The  introduction  of  "establishment," 
or  time  wages,  was  an  innovation  of  the  employers  at  the  beginning  of  the  present 
century,  consented  to  by  the  operatives  with  much  reluctance,  and  denounced  by 
some  of  them  as  leading  to  reduction  of  rates.      (See  Place  MSS.  27,799-99/103.) 
The  acceptance  of  both  systems  of  remuneration  has  involved  the  enactment  of 
various  subsidiary  rules  to  check  unfair  wages  calculated  to  depress  rates.     Thus 
employers  are  not  allowed  to  change  from  one  system   to  another  without  due 
notice,  as  otherwise  the  operative  would  be  required  to  do  all  difficult  composition 
by  the  piece,  the   "fat"   (or   profitable  work)  being  given  out  at  time  wages. 
Elaborate  arrangements  are  made   for   the   fair   distribution  of  "  the  fat,"  the 
"clicker"   who  hands    out    the    "copy"    to   the    different    compositors    being 
appointed  and  frequently  paid  by  the  "chapel,"  the  ancient  organisation  of  the 
workmen  in  each   printing  office.      Many  disputes  have  arisen  from  employers 
attempting  to  withhold  "the  fat"  from  the  piecework  compositors;  or,  on  the 
other  hand,    to  use   the   pieceworkers  to   force   the   pace  of  the   timeworkers. 
Compositors'  unions  therefore  prefer  that  the  employer  should  confine  himself  to 
one  system  or  the  other. 

In  1876  a  joint  committee  of  the  Glasgow  master  printers  and  their  com- 
positors decided  that  the  "clicking  system,"  or  fair  sharing  of  the  "fat,"  was 


3OO  Trade  Union  Function 

of  ordinary  book  matter  and  daily  newspaper  work  is  done 
by  the  piece,  whereas  corrections  and  special  jobs  difficult  of 
calculation  are  done  by  "  stab  "  men. 

The  other  leading  instance  of  an  impartial  acceptance 
of  both  piecework  and  time  wages  is  offered  by  the  United 
Society  of  Boilermakers  and  Iron-shipbuilders.  Here  the 
bulk  of  the  work  in  building  new  ships  is  done  by  the  piece, 
at  rates  settled,  as  we  have  already  mentioned,  between  the 
district  committee  of  the  union  and  the  particular  firms  or 
the  local  employers'  association.  On  the  other  hand,  repair- 
ing work,  which  cannot  be  classified  in  advance,  is  done  at 
time  wages.  Thus  the  by-laws  for  the  Mersey  district 
declare  that  "  piecework  of  any  description  is  not  allowed  on 
repair  jobs  in  either  wet  or  dry  docks  ;  and  no  man  shall  be 
in  any  way  compelled  to  put  in  any  given  number  of  rivets, 
or  tasked  as  to  other  work,  which  he  shall  do  during  the 
day  ;  but  in  all  cases,  the  principle  of  a  fair  day's  work  for 
a  fair  day's  pay  be  faithfully  and  honorably  carried  out  by 
every  member  of  this  Association." l  We  see  the  same 
distinction  unconsciously  influencing  another  trade,  the  Tin- 
plate  Workers,  who,  less  fortunate  than  the  Boilermakers, 
have  not  succeeded  in  organising  their  whole  trade  into  a 
single  society.  The  General  Union  of  Tinplate  Workers, 
with  Liverpool  for  its  headquarters,  whose  work  is  mainly 
connected  with  shipbuilding,  and  is  so  diverse  as  to  render  it 
difficult,  if  not  impossible,  to  construct  any  piecework  list, 
insists  on  time  wages.  On  the  other  hand,  the  National 
Amalgamated  Tinplate  Workers'  Union,  with  its  headquarters 
at  Wolverhampton,  which  comprises  mainly  the  artificers 
of  sheet  metal  pots  and  pans,  has  a  regular  list  of  prices,  and 
prefers  to  work  by  the  piece.  So  closely  does  this  difference 
of  policy  coincide  with  difference  of  work  that  the  Manchester 
Branch  of  the  General  Union  (the  shipyard  society),  which 

equivalent  to  an  addition  to  a  farthing  per  1000,  this  advance  being  conceded  to 
the  compositors  in  shops  where  that  system  did  not  prevail. — MS.  Minutes  of 
Glasgow  Typographical  Society,  I2th  December  1876. 

1  By-laws  for  the  Mersey  District   United  Society  of  Boilermakers  and  Iron- 
shipbuilders  (Liverpool,  1889). 


The  Standard  Rate  301 

finds  itself  by  exception  employed  in  the  fashioning  of  pots 
and  pans,  refuses  to  abide  by  the  principle  of  time  work 
followed  by  the  port  branches,  and  elects  to  work  by  the 
piece.  In  both  cases  the  aim  is  the  same,  namely  the  main- 
tenance of  a  Standard  Rate.  But  the  difference  of  policy 
between  the  two  societies,  arising,  as  can  be  seen,  from  the 
difference  in  their  respective  tasks,  is  not  clearly  understood 
by  either,  and  is  the  subject  of  constant  friction  between 
lem.  And  so  it  happens  that  (forgetting  the  example  of 
its  own  Manchester  Branch)  the  General  Union  of  Tin- 
plate  Workers  accuses  the  National  Amalgamated  Tinplate 
Corkers'  Union  of  betraying  the  central  position  of  Trade 
Unionism  by  not  insisting  on  time  wages.  On  the  other 
ind,  the  latter  society,  confident  in  its  piecework  lists,  sees 
10  reason  why  it  should  not  establish  branches  of  piece- 
workers in  the  ports,  where  time  work  has  hitherto  prevailed, 
ind  where  piecework  would  probably  break  down  all  Collec- 
ive  Bargaining. 

This  instance  indicates  how  unconscious  particular  Trade 
Unions  may  be  of  the  principles  upon  which  their  empirical 
iction  has  really  been  based.  The  same  unconsciousness 
>metimes  leads  to  a  persistence  in  whichever  method  of 
remuneration  has  been  customary,  long  after  the  circum- 
tances  have  changed.  Thus  the  Cabinetmakers,  among 
whom  Collective  Bargaining  in  any  elaborate  form  has  prac- 
tically disappeared,  might  possibly  have  maintained  their 
>rganisation  if  they  had,  like  the  Bricklayers  and  Stone- 
lasons,  insisted  on  reverting  to  time  wages.  At  the  begin- 
ning of  this  century,  the  Cabinetmakers  had  elaborate  lists 
of  prices,  collectively  agreed  to  between  employers  and 
employed  ;  and  we  have  ample  evidence  of  the  efficiency 
with  which  the  contemporary  cabinetmakers'  unions  conducted 
their  Collective  Bargaining.  In  consequence  of  the  great 
changes  in  and  multiplication  of  patterns,  and  the  alteration 
of  processes,  the  lists  have  long  since  been  obsolete,  and  no 
one  has  yet  found  it  possible  to  classify  the  innumerable  jobs 
now  involved  in  the  manufacture  of  furniture.  "  Estimate 


302  Trade  Union  Function 

work,""  lump  work,"  and  other  forms  of  the  individual  bargain 
accordingly  prevail.  So  strong,  however,  has  been  the  tradi- 
tion and  custom  of  piecework  in  the  trade  that  none  of  the 
various  unions  which  have  from  time  to  time  arisen  during 
the  last  half  century  have  been  able  to  stand  out  for  time 
wages.  Collective  action  accordingly  now  seldom  rises  higher 
than  the  "  shop  bargain,"  and  even  this  frequently  breaks 
down. 

Another  instance  of  a  customary  adherence  to  a  tradi- 
tional method  of  remuneration  is  to  be  found  in  the  Iron- 
founders'  and  Engineers'  rigid  refusal  to  recognise  piecework 
even  on  those  jobs  which  involve  the  constant  repetition  of 
precisely  the  same  operation.  We  have  already  explained 
why  the  bulk  of  the  work  in  an  engineering  shop  cannot  be 
done  at  piecework  rates  consistently  with  Collective  Bargain- 
ing. But  with  the  enormous  expansion  of  the  trade,  and  the 
application  of  machinery  to  particular  processes,  a  considerable 
section  of  engineers  and  "  machine  moulders  "  have  long  found 
themselves  turning  out  a  constant  succession  of  identical 
articles  for  which  it  would  be  quite  practicable  to  frame  a 
uniform  piecework  list  which  would  allow  of  Collective 
Bargaining.  So  strong,  however,  was  the  traditional  feeling 
of  the  mechanics  against  piecework  (meaning  "  estimate  work  " 
and  Individual  Bargaining)  that  the  Amalgamated  Society 
of  Engineers  positively  refused,  down  to  1892,  to  allow  any 
employer  to  introduce  any  piecework  whatsoever,  with  the 
consequence  that  establishment  after  establishment  became 
closed  to  the  union.  At  last,  at  their  quinquennial  "  Parlia- 
ment "in  1892,  the  Engineers  decided  to  permit  the  formation 
of  piecework  lists,  in  the  cases  in  which  they  were  practicable, 
and  appointed  salaried  officers  to  carry  out  this  new  form  of 
Collective  Bargaining.  The  Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders 
still  refuses  to  take  this  step,  with  the  result  that  the  auto- 
matic machine  process  of  casting  has  fallen  to  a  separate 
class  of  workmen,  who  are  not  eligible  for  membership  to 
this  old-established  union. 

We  are  now  in  a  position  to  come  to  some  general  con- 


The  Standard  Rate  303 

elusion  as  to  the  attitude  which  Trade  Unions  take  up  with 
regard  to  piecework  and  time  work.  It  is  not  true  that 
Trade  Unions  object  to  piecework  as  such  ;  in  fact,  a  majority 
of  Trade  Unionists  either  willingly  accept,  or  else  positively 
insist  on,  that  system  of  remuneration.  Nor  is  it  true  that 
employers  universally  prefer  piecework.  The  members  of 
the  great  race  of  sub-contractors  in  all  industries  are  always 
trying  to  employ  time  workers,  in  order  to  obtain  for  them- 
selves the  fullest  possible  advantage  of  their  own  driving 
power.  In  the  same  way,  employers  whose  machinery  is 
rapidly  improving  complain  of  the  inequity  of  the  piecework 
system,  as  being  apt  to  deprive  them  of  part  of  the  advantage 
of  an  increase  in  the  speed  of  working.  What  the  capitalist 
seeks  is  to  get  more  work  for  the  old  pay.  Sometimes  this 
can  be  achieved  best  by  piecework,  sometimes  by  time  work. 
Workmen,  on  the  other  hand,  strive  to  obtain  more  pay  for 
the  same  number  of  working  hours.  For  the  moment,  at 
any  rate,  the  individual  operative  can  most  easily  secure  this 
by  piecework.  But  not  even  for  the  sake  of  getting  more 
pay  for  the  same  number  of  hours'  work  will  the  experienced 
workman  revert  to  the  individual  bargain,  with  all  its  dangers. 
Accordingly  the  Trade  Unions  accept  piecework  only  when 
it  is  consistent  with  Collective  Bargaining,  that  is,  when  a 
standard  list  of  prices  can  be  arrived  at  between  the  em- 
ployers on  the  one  hand,  and  the  representatives  of  the  whole 
body  of  workmen  on  the  other.  As  a  matter  of  fact  this  is 
practicable,  so  far  as  concerns  anything  above  mere  unskilled . 
laboring,  in  a  majority  of  the  organised  industries,  in  which, 
therefore,  piecework  prevails  by  consent  of  both  masters  and 
men.  It  is,  indeed,  impossible  to  decide  whether  Trade 
Unionism  has,  on  the  whole,  favored  or  discouraged  the 
substitution  of  piecework  for  time  wages.  On  the  one  hand, 
every  increase  in  Trade  Union  organisation,  and  especially 
every  extension  of  the  class  of  salaried  Trade  Union  officials, 
has  made  more  possible  the  arrangement  of  definite  piecework 
lists.  This  process  is  now  extending  from  trade  to  trade. 
The  very  establishment  of  these  lists  has,  on  the  other  hand, 


304  Trade  Union  Function 

lessened  the  employers'  desire  to  introduce  piecework,  whilst 
to  any  method  of  remuneration  involving  individual  bargain- 
ing, such  as  "  estimate  "  or  "  lump  "  work,  the  Trade  Unions 
have  shown  implacable  hostility. 

And  just  as  the  fundamental  idea  of  the  Standard  Rate 
has  enabled  us  to  understand  the  Trade  Union  attitude 
towards  piecework,  so,  too,  we  shall  find  it  throwing  light 
upon  various  minor  regulations  of  particular  Trade  Unions. 
Various  unions  of  operatives  working  at  time  wages  have  from 
time  to  time  attempted  to  secure  a  real,  as  distinguished  from 
a  nominal  identity  in  the  rate  of  remuneration,  by  fixing,  not 
merely  the  minimum  money  wage,  but  also  the  maximum 
amount  of  work  to  be  done  for  that  wage.  Some  of  these 
rules  have  obtained  notoriety  as  classic  instances  of  the  folly 
and  perversity  of  Trade  Unions.  The  fifth  by-law  of  the 
Bradford  Lodge  of  the  Laborers'  Union  of  1867  was  quoted 
before  the  Trade  Union  Commission  as  follows  :  "  You  are 
strictly  cautioned  not  to  outstep  good  rules  by  doing  double 
the  work  you  are  required,  and  causing  others  to  do  the  same, 
in  order  to  gain  a  smile  from  the  master."  l  And  the  fol- 
lowing rule  of  the  Leeds  Lodge  of  the  Bricklayers'  Laborers' 
Union  was  at  the  same  time  given  :  "  Any  brother  in  the 
Union  professing  to  carry  any  more  than  the  common 
number,  which  is  eight  bricks,  shall  be  fined  one  shilling,  to 
be  paid  within  one  month,  or  remain  out  of  the  benefit  until 
such  fine  be  paid."2  Nor  were  such  rules  entirely  confined 
to  unskilled  laborers.  The  Manchester  Bricklayers'  Associ- 
ation were  stated,  in  1869,  to  have  a  rule  providing  that 
"  Any  man  found  running  or  working  beyond  a  regular  speed 
shall  be  fined  2s.  6d.  for  the  first  offence,  5s.  for  the  second, 
I  os.  for  the  third,  and  if  still  persisting,  shall  be  dealt  with 
as  the  Committee  think  proper."  3  The  Friendly  Society  of 
Operative  Stonemasons  adopted,  in  1865,  the  following  rule  : 

1  Evidence  of  Mr.  A.  Mault,  Secretary  of  the  Manchester  Builders'  Associa- 
tion.^ Q.  3120. 

Ibid.     Q.  3122. 
3  \V.  T.  Thornton,  On  Labour  (London,  1869),  pp.  350,  351. 


The  Standard  Rate  305 

"  In  localities  where  that  most  obnoxious  and  destructive 
system  generally  known  as  '  chasing '  is  persisted  in,  lodges 
should  use  every  effort  to  put  it  down.  Not  to  take  less 
time  than  that  taken  by  an  average  mason  in  the  execution 
of  the  first  portion  of  each  description  of  work  is  the  practice 
that  should  be  adopted  among  us  as  much  as  possible ;  and 
where  it  is  plainly  visible  that  any  member  or  other  in- 
dividual is  striving  to  overwork  or  *  chase '  his  fellow-work- 
men, thereby  acting  in  a  manner  calculated  to  lead  to  the 
discharge  of  members  or  a  reduction  of  their  wages,  the  party 
so  acting  shall  be  summoned  before  the  lodge,  and  if  the 
charge  be  satisfactorily  proved  a  fine  shall  be  inflicted."  1 

These  and  similar  regulations,  widely  advertised  by  the 
Trade  Union  Commission  of  1867-69,  met  with  universal 
condemnation.  It  does  not  seem  to  have  been  perceived 
that,  however  bad  were  their  secondary  results,  they  were,  in 
their  inception,  a  necessary  protection  of  any  Standard  Rate 
upon  a  time-work  basis.  It  is  a  necessary  incident  of  the 
collective  bargain  that  one  man  should  not  underbid  another  ; 
and  this  underbidding  can  as  easily  take  place  by  the  offer 
of  more  work  for  the  same  hour's  wage,  as  by  the  offer  of 
the  normal  amount  of  work  for  a  lower  hourly  wage.  By 
underbidding  in  the  hourly  rate,  this  would  be  lowered  for 
all.  It  follows  equally  that  by  underbidding  in  point  of  the 
intensity  of  effort,  this  would,  in  the  same  way,  soon  be 
raised  for  all.  But  the  workmen's  by-laws  were  designed 
also  to  meet  a  more  insidious  attack.  Many  pushing  fore- 
men, in  building  contracts,  intent  on  getting  the  utmost  work 
out  of  their  men,  were  accustomed  to  bribe  particular  work- 
men with  beer,  or  by  the  promise  of  a  slightly  increased  rate 
of  pay,  to  work  at  exceptional  speed,  with  the  object  of 
"pulling  on"  all  the  other  workmen  to  the  same  speed. 
These  "  bell  horses,"  as  they  were  termed  by  the  workmen, 
were,  in  fact,  used  to  increase  the  intensity  of  the  work  be- 
yond the  normal  standard  tacitly  implied  in  the  collective 

1  Rule   n,  Class  2,  p.   31,  in  Laws  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Operative 
Stonemasons  (Bolton,  1867). 

VOL.  I  X 


306  Trade  Union  Function 

bargain,  much  in  the  same  way  as  the  pieceworking  Butty 
Master  forced  the  speed  of  the  time-working  coal  hewer. 
The  practice  was,  in  fact,  a  method  of  obtaining  extra  work 
from  the  whole  gang,  whilst  paying  only  one  or  two  men  in 
the  gang  for  the  extra  exertion  involved.  When  done  with- 
out the  men's  knowledge,  the  practice  amounted  to  a  fraudu- 
lent evasion  of  the  bargain. 

Such  practices  on  the  part  of  employers  and  their  foremen 
would  quickly  have  rendered  a  Standard  Rate  and  Collective 
Bargaining  impossible,  and  it  was  not  unnatural  that  the 
workmen  should  have  adopted  regulations  in  their  own  de- 
fence. The  coal  hewers  and  the  strikers,  exposed,  as  we  have 
seen,  to  being  similarly  "  driven,"  met  the  attack  by  insisting 
on  themselves  receiving  piecework  rates.  The  cotton-spinners 
and  cotton-weavers  protected  themselves  against  the  constant 
"  speeding  up  "  of  the  machinery  by  elaborating  their  piece- 
work lists.  The  builder's  laborer  whose  fetch  and  carry 
work  could  hardly  be  paid  by  the  piece  could  find  no  other 
expedient  than  fixing  by  collective  agreement  the  maximum 
task  as  well  as  the  minimum  wage. 

But  if  the  use  of  "  bell  horses  "  is  a  fraud  on  the  men, 
the  regulations  devised  to  check  this  practice  may  easily 
work  out  so  as  to  be  a  fraud  on  the  employer.  He  has,  in 
effect,  contracted  for  his  labor  at  an  all-round  rate,  on  the 
assumption  that  he  receives  a  normal  average  of  work.  In 
the  group  of  workmen  there  will,  of  course,  be  some  of 
average  speed,  together  with  a  few  quicker  men,  and  a  few 
slower.  Any  regulations  which  tend  to  restrict  the  quick 
workers  necessarily  lower  the  average  of  the  whole,  upon 
which  the  collective  bargain  has  by  implication  been  based. 

This  practice  of  "  levelling  down  "  the  quantity  of  labor 
is  seen  at  its  worst  when  it  is  used  as  a  weapon  not  of 
defence  but  of  aggression.  It  is  one  thing  to  prohibit  indi- 
vidual workmen  from  allowing  themselves  to  be  used  as  a 
means  of  exacting  unpaid  extra  labor  from  their  fellows.  It 
would  be  quite  another  matter  if  Trade  Unions,  unable  to 
raise  the  sum  of  their  wages,  advocated  to  all  their  members 


The  Standard  Rate  307 

an  insidious  diminution  of  their  energy  without  notice  to  the 
employer.  This  might  be  as  much  a  fraudulent  alteration  of 
the  implied  bargain  as  the  practice  of  the  Butty  Master.  We 
know  of  one  case  of  this  nature,  the  so-called  "  go  canny" 
policy,  adopted  for  a  short  time  by  the  National  Union  of 
Dock  Laborers  in  Liverpool.  The  employers  had  stead- 
fastly refused  to  increase  the  remuneration  for  their  low-paid 
work,  and  the  men  found  themselves  powerless  to  obtain 
what  they  considered  a  living  wage.  In  desperation  they 
adopted  the  expedient  of  not  putting  any  energy  into  their 
work.  In  this  somewhat  remarkable  case  the  laborers 
alleged  that  they  were  only  following  the  practice  of  the 
commercial  man.  "  There  is  no  ground  for  doubting,"  observed 
the  report  of  their  executive  committee,  "  that  the  real  rela- 
tion of  the  employer  to  the  workman  is  simply  this — to  secure 
the  largest  amount  of  the  best  kind  of  work  for  the  smallest 
wages  ;  and,  undesirable  as  this  relation  may  be  to  the  work- 
man, there  is  no  escape  from  it  except  to  adopt  the  situation 
and  apply  it  to  the  common-sense  commercial  rule  which 
provides  a  commodity  in  accordance  with  the  price.  .  .  .  The 
employer  insists  upon  fixing  the  amount  he  will  give  for 
an  hour's  labor  without  the  slightest  consideration  for  the 
laborer ;  there  is,  surely,  therefore,  nothing  wrong  in  the 
laborer,  on  the  other  hand,  fixing  the  amount  and  the 
quality  of  the  labor  he  will  give  in  an  hour  for  the  price 
fixed  by  the  employer.  If  employers  of  labor  or  purchasers 
of  goods  refuse  to  pay  for  the  genuine  article^  they  must  be 
content  with  shoddy  and  veneer.  This  is  their  own  orthodox 
doctrine  which  they  urge  us  to  study." x 

From  the  old  standpoint  of  a  purely  competitive  indi- 
vidualism, it  is  not  easy  to  deny  the  men's  right  to  sell  an 
adulterated  form  of  labor  if  they  think  it  to  their  advantage 

1  Report  of  Executive  of  the  National  Union  of  Dock  Laborers  in  Great  Britain 
and  Ireland,  1891  (Glasgow,  1891,  pp.  14-15).  The  men  quoted  the  following 
sentence  from  Jevons's  Primer  of  Political  Economy :  "  The  employer,  generally 
speaking,  is  right  in  getting  work  done  at  the  lowest  possible  cost ;  and  if  there 
is  a  supply  of  labor  forthcoming  at  lower  rates  of  wages,  it  would  not  be  wise  in 
him  to  pay  higher  rates." 


308  Trade  Union  Function 

to  do  so.  If,  as  in  the  instance  cited,  the  men  openly  pro- 
claim their  intention,  there  is  no  question  of  fraud  ;  and  they 
may,  from  this  point  of  view,  fairly  claim  to  be  acting  like 
an  exceptionally  honest  trader  who,  whilst  selling  shoddy 
goods,  does  not  pretend  that  they  are  anything  else.  The 
employers  may  retaliate  by  dismissal.  The  men  may,  in 
return,  persuade  their  successors  to  adopt  the  same  method. 
The  quarrel  becomes  a  "  struggle  for  existence,"  in  which 
the  "  fittest "  in  these  arts  of  war  may  survive. 

We  have,  however,  come  to  believe  that  in  such  inter- 
necine struggles  the  interests  of  the  community  as  a  whole 
almost  inevitably  suffer.  In  spite  of  the  protests  of  John 
Bright,  successive  Parliaments  have  prohibited  the  adultera- 
tion of  commodities.  But  adulteration  of  labor  is  infinitely 
more  injurious  to  the  community.  We  have,  in  fact,  in  this 
case  a  striking  illustration  of  the  utter  fallacy  of  the  statement 
that  "  labor  is  a  commodity,  ...  an  article  saleable  and  pur- 
chaseable,"  which  could  not  logically  be  treated  "  as  any- 
thing else."  l  We  cannot  separate  the  quantity  or  quality  of 
the  day's  work  from  its  effect  upon  the  health  and  character  of 
the  human  being  who  is  rendering  it.  The  sub-contractor's 
practice  of  "  driving,"  the  constant  pressure  upon  a  man  to 
work  always  at  the  very  top  of  his  speed,  will  quickly  break 
down  the  health  of  the  worker,  and  impoverish  the  nation  by 
producing  premature  old  age.  On  the  other  hand,  systematic 
loitering  will  destroy  the  character  and  efficiency  of  even  the 
most  resolute  worker.  In  adulterating  the  product,  you 
adulterate  the  man.  To  the  unskilled  laborers  of  a  great 
city,  already  demoralised  by  irregularity  of  employment  and 
reduced  below  the  average  in  capacity  for  persistent  work, 
the  doctrine  of  "  go  canny"  may  easily  bring  about  the  final 
ruin  of  personal  character.  It  was  an  instinctive  apprecia- 
tion of  this  truth  which  led  the  responsible  Trade  Union 
officials  unhesitatingly  to  denounce  the  new  departure  of  the 

1  Speech  of  the  well-known  capitalist  opponent  of  Trade  Unions,  Edmund 
Potter  of  Manchester,  Social  Science  Association's  Report  on  Trade  Societies  and 
Strikes,  1860,  p.  603. 


The  Standard  Rate  309 

Liverpool  dock  laborers.      It  remains,  so  far  as  we  know,  a 
unique  instance  in  Trade  Union  annals. l 

When  we  turn  from  time  workers  to  pieceworkers,  we 
find  the  subsidiary  regulations  called  into  being  to  defend  the 
Standard  Rate  wholly  free  from  any  objectionable  character, 
beyond  a  certain  inevitable  complexity.  The  first  series  of 
these  is  concerned  with  accuracy  of  measurement.  Employers 
have  always  claimed  the  right  of  making,  by  their  agents  or 
themselves,  all  the  calculations  involved  in  preparing  their 
pay  sheets,  and  they  have  expected  the  operatives  implicitly 
to  accept  their  figures.  Against  this  contention  the  Trade 
Unions  have  persistently  and  successfully  struggled.  In  all 
the  cases  in  which  the  operative  is  unable  easily  to  check 
the  computation,  it  is  obvious  that  such  an  arrangement  left 
the  Standard  Rate  entirely  at  the  master's  mercy.  "  In  weigh- 
ing how  was  the  collier  to  obtain  justice  ?  He  was  at  the 
bottom  of  the  pit,  and  could  not  see  the  master's  nominee  at 
the  top — and  so  again  there  arose  the  cry  of  being  cheated 
in  weight.  For  years  this  was  a  bone  of  contention  ;  and 
in  revising  the  Inspections  (Mines  Regulation)  Act  of  1860, 
the  delegates  of  the  men  prevailed  upon  the  Government  to 
insert  a  clause,  ordering  that  coal  should  be  duly  weighed 
by  a  just  steelyard  at  the  pit's  mouth,  and  that  the  men 
might,  at  their  own  cost,  appoint  a  checkweigh-man  who 
should  not  further  interfere  with  the  working  but  to  see  and 
take  an  account  of  the  men's  work.  Opposition  to  this  clause 
was  strongly  offered  by  the  delegates  of  the  employers  .  .  . 
the  masters  did  not  want  a  weighing  clause  at  all.  ...  A 
compromise  was  submitted  to.  The  weighing  clause  was 
incorporated  with  another  clause — the  2Qth — with  a  rider 

1  It  is  only  fair  to  Trade  Union  officials  to  say  that  the  two  enthusiasts  who, 
in  despair  of  otherwise  benefiting  the  unfortunate  laborers,  initiated  this  policy, 
did  not  belong  to  the  ranks  of  the  workmen — a  fact  which  the  reader  of  their 
able  and  ingenious  argument  will  already  have  perceived.  They  were  shortly 
afterwards  formally  excluded,  as  middle-class  men,  from  the  Trade  Union  Con- 
gress at  Glasgow  in  1892.  When,  in  1896,  it  was  suggested  that  a  similar  policy 
should  be  adopted  by  the  International  Federation  of  Ship,  Dock,  and  River 
Workers,  it  was  opposed  by  such  leaders  as  Ben  Tillett,  and  rejected  by  the 
members'  vote. 


310  Trade  Union  Function 

added  to  it  by  the  employers,  viz.  that  the  checkweigh-man 
should  be  selected  from  persons  employed  at  that  colliery." 1 

Without  casting  any  special  imputation  on  coalowners, 
it  may  be  said  that  the  miners'  suspicions  have  been  so  far 
borne  out  by  evidence  that  Parliament  has  progressively 
strengthened  the  clause  thus  adopted  in  1860.  As  the  law 
now  stands,  a  simple  majority  of  the  miners  in  any  one  pit 
can  decide  to  have  a  checkweigh-man  elected  by  the  pit,  and 
paid  by  a  compulsory  stoppage  from  the  earnings  of  every 
pieceworker  employed,  including  even  those  who  voted  against 
the  proposal.  Any  person  who  is  or  has  been  a  miner  may 
be  elected  to  the  post,  whether  the  employer  likes  it  or  not, 
and  the  law  courts  insist  that  he  shall  be  allowed  free  access 
to  the  weighing  machines,  and  given  every  facility  for  check- 
ing the  weights. 

A  further  step  in  the  same  direction  has  been  taken  at 
the  instance  of  the  powerful  unions  of  cotton  operatives. 
What  the  coal  miners  have  obtained  is  the  right  to  have  the 
employers'  calculations  checked  by  the  men's  official.  The 
textile  operatives  have  obtained,  not  only  the  publication  in 
advance  by  the  employer  of  the  exact  particulars  on  which 
he  will  calculate  the  piecework  earnings,  but  have  also  secured 
the  appointment  of  a  Government  officer  specially  charged 
with  seeing  that  these  particulars  are  correctly  stated.2  The 
"particulars  clause,"  adopted  for  cotton -weavers  in  the 
Factory  Act  of  the  Conservative  Government  of  1891,  and 
extended  to  all  textile  workers  by  the  amending  Act  of  the 
Liberal  Government  of  1895,  will,  in  all  probability,  be 
applied,  within  a  few  years,  to  all  piecework  trades  in  which 
the  computation  of  earnings  lends  itself  to  mistake  or  fraud.8 

1  Transactions  and  Results  of  the  National  Association  of  Coal,  Lime,  and 
Ironstone  Miners  of  Great  Britain  (London,  1863),  p.  vii. 

2  It  is  much  to  the  credit  of  the  North-East  Lancashire  Operative  Weavers' 
Association,  and  to  the  fair-mindedness  of  the  leading  employers,  that  the  veteran 
official  of  the  weavers'  union,  who  had  for  a  generation  fought  the  men's  battles, 
was,  by  common  consent,  marked  out  as  the  fittest  person  to  hold  this  important 
new  office.     Mr.  T.  Birtwistle  has  fully  justified  his  appointment,  and  has  given 
universal  satisfaction  to  all  parties. 

3  The  Factory  Act  of  1895  empowers  the   Home  Secretary  to  apply  this 


The  Standard  Rate  311 

By  this  clause  the  employer  is  required  to  state  in  writing, 
before  the  job  is  begun,  all  the  particulars  (including  the  rate 
of  payment)  required  for  the  precise  computation  of  the 
operatives'  earnings. 

But  there  are  other  ways  of  defrauding  the  pieceworker 
besides  inaccurate  calculations.  The  weight  of  coal  hewn  by 
each  miner  may  be  accurately  measured  at  the  pit's  mouth, 
but  if  he  is  sent  to  work  in  a  distant  or  difficult  seam,  the 
standard  tonnage  rate  may  be  very  far  from  securing  identical 
pay  for  identical  effort.  The  cotton-spinner  finds  his  list  of 
prices  a  delusion  if  his  mules  have  to  be  frequently  stopped 
to  repair  breakages  caused  by  the  bad  quality  of  the  raw 
cotton.  And  even  those  who  are  aware  of  the  coalminers' 
"  county  basis,"  and  of  the  elaborate  "  cotton  lists,"  seldom 
realise  how  technical  and  how  minute  are  the  adjustments 
which  are  necessary  to  attain  this  end,  or  how  manifold  and 
incessant  are  the  complaints  requiring  attention.  The  best 
way  of  bringing  the  facts  home  to  the  general  reader  will, 
we  think,  be  to  give  a  few  extracts  from  actual  proceedings. 
Thus,  the  Joint  Committee  of  the  Northumberland  Coal- 
owners  and  Miners  settled,  in  a  single  day,  the  following  as 
well  as  many  other  cases  : — 

Burradon. — Agreement  confirmed.  Yard  Seam,  East  Side,  until 
end  of  current  quarter,  is.  7^d.  per  ton  ;  afterwards  is.  6jd.  per  ton. 

Cramlington,  Amelia  Pit. — Agreement  confirmed  :  (a)  Yankee  Jack 
system  shall  be  abolished  whenever  the  owners  find  it  convenient  to  do 
so,  and  upon  such  abolition  the  hewing  prices  in  the  Low  Main  and  Yard. 
Seams  shall  be  advanced  9  per  cent.  In  the  case  of  the  Main  Coal 
Seam  the  unscreened  hewing  prices  shall  be  63  per  cent  of  the  present 
round  coal  hewing  prices,  and  upon  such  abolition  they  shall  be  advanced 
9  per  cent. 

Walker. — Agreement  confirmed.  Beaumont  and  Brockwell  Seams. 
Long  wall  or  broken  hewing  price  shall  be  paid  when  40  yards  from 
commencement  of  long  wall,  i.e.  40  yards  from  fast  wall  side. 

New  Backworth. — Men  request  payment  for  lamps  when  required  to 
use  them  in  the  whole.  To  be  paid  extra  id.  per  ton  in  bord  and  pillar 

clause,  by  mere  administrative  order,  to  any  piecework  trade,  and  it  was  so 
applied  in  1897  to  manufacturies  of  handkerchiefs,  aprons,  pinafores,  and  blouses ; 
and  to  those  of  chains,  anchors,  and  locks. 


312  Trade  Union  Function 

whole  workings,  in  accordance  with  county  arrangement,  when  required 
to  use  lamps. 

Seaton  Burn. — Owners  desire  hewing  price  for  long  wall  in  Bowes' 
coal  in  Low  Main  Seam  to  be  fixed.  That  standard  prices  now  being 
paid  be  reduced  3d.  per  ton.1 

Even  more  diversified  are  the  adjustments  of  the  cotton 
operatives.  Here  are  some  extracts  from  the  diary  of  the 
secretary  of  the  Bolton  spinners  : — 

January  5th,  1892. — Mr.  Pennington,  of  the  Hindley  Twist  Com- 
pany, Hindley,  called  here  this  morning.  He  agreed  to  weekly  pays, 
and  to  discontinue  the  system  of  one  spinner  to  two  pairs  of  mules.  I 
am  to  go  through  the  mills  on  Monday  next,  and  if  spinning  is  not  satis- 
factory, will  be  made  so ;  and  we  are  to  see  in  what  way  the  mules  can 
be  speeded  up  so  as  to  give  better  wages.  Work  is  to  be  resumed  on 
Thursday  morning. 

January  6th.— Went  to  Peake's  Place  Mill  (Messrs.  Tristram's), 
Halliwell,  and  arranged  that  the  men  on  the  three  pairs  of  mules 
spinning  coarse  counts  shall  receive  2s.  6d.  a  week  extra,  until  certain 
alterations  and  repairs  to  the  mules  shall  have  been  made. 

January  6th. — Accompanied  by  Mr.  Percival  (the  secretary  of  the 
employers'  association),  I  went  to  Mr.  Robert  Briercliffe's  Mill,  Moses 
Gate.  They  have  no  less  rims  in  stock,  so  it  was  agreed  that  the  prices 
per  100  Ibs.  for  spinning  in  No.  I  Mill  shall  be  increased  6d.  for  one 
month  during  which  the  work  is  to  be  made  satisfactory.  The  firm 
have  likewise  conceded  the  request  of  their  men,  and  will  adopt  payment 
by  indicator.  The  notice  to  leave  work  is  consequently  withdrawn. 

January  8th. — Complaints  are  to  hand  from  Messrs.  M'Connell  and 
Co.'s  Sedgwick  Mill,  Manchester,  of  bobbins  breaking ;  being  short  of 
doffing  tins ;  and  of  the  men  on  six  pairs  of  mules  being  unable  to  earn 
the  basis  wages. 

January  1 2th. — From  our  men  at  Waterloo  Mill,  Bolton,  comes  a 
complaint  of  the  rooms  being  too  cold,  and  also  irregular  running  of  the 
engine. 

January  iQth. — Have  tested  the  counts  at  Melrose  Mill,  and  found 
the  average  2^  hanks  wrong.  The  men  are  to  leave  work  at  breakfast 
time  to-morrow  if  counts  are  not  put  right. 

April  7th,  1893. — Mr.  Percival  and  myself,  at  the  request  of  Messrs. 
James  Marsden  and  Sons,  went  through  their  No.  4  Mill  to  look  at  the 
spinning  on  the  counts  complained  of  on  Tuesday.  We  found  it  below 
the  usual  standard  at  this  firm,  and  Mr.  Joseph  Marsden  undertook  to 
see  to  its  rectification. 

1  Proceedings  of  Joint  Committee  on  I4th  November  1891  (Northumberland 
Miners'  Minutes t  1891). 


The  Standard  Rate  313 

April  loth. — Want  of  window  blinds  is  the  complaint  from  our  men 
at  the  Parkside  Mill,  Golborne. 

April  1 8th. — Our  members  at  Messrs.  Robert  Haworth,  Ltd.,  Castle 
Hill  Mill,  Hindley,  complain  of  the  overbearing  conduct  of  their  over- 
looker. On  investigation,  found  that  they  were  more  to  blame  than 
the  overlooker. 

May  Qth. — The  drosophore  humidifier  at  Robin  Hood,  No.  2  Mill, 
is  so  detrimental  to  the  health  of  the  men  that  I  am  to  request  the  firm 
not  to  use  it  further. 

June  1 2th. — Mr.  Percival,  Mr.  Robinson,  and  myself  went  to  Howe- 
bridge  Mills  to  test  counts  in  No.  2  Mill.  We  found  them  fully  one 
hank  finer  than  are  paid  for.  The  firm  promise  to  put  them  right,  but 
that  is  not  sufficient  for  us,  as  they  will  be  wrong  again  before  the  week 
end.  We  suggested  they  should  adopt  payment  by  indicator,  and  the 
firm  subsequently  agreed  to  try  a  few  pairs.1 

We  see  the  same  determination  to  obtain  identical  pay- 
ment for  identical  effort  in  the  Trade  Union  regulations 
enforcing  specific  additions  for  extra  exertion  or  incon- 
venience. Hence  the  "  Working  Rules,"  drawn  up  in  almost 
every  town  by  the  master  builders  and  the  several  sections 
of  building  operatives,  include,  besides  the  standard  rate 
for  the  normal  hours  and  ordinary  work,  determinate  charges 
for  "  walking  time  "  beyond  a  certain  distance,  and  "  lodging 
money "  when  sent  away  from  home.2  In  trades  in  which  ^ 
men  provide  their  own  steel  tools,  "  grinding  money "  is  a 
usual  extra.8  When  any  class  of  work  involves  special  un- 
pleasantness or  injury  to  clothing,  "  black  money  "  or  "  dirty 
money  "  is  sometimes  stipulated  for.  Thus,  the  boilermakers 
and  engineers  receive  extra  rates  for  jobs  connected  with 
oil-carrying  vessels.  "  Men  working  inside  the  ballast-tanks  or 
between  the  deep  floors  under  the  engine-beds,  after  the  vessel 
has  been  regularly  employed  at  sea,  to  receive  one  quarter 

1  These  diaries  are  printed  in  the  Annual  Reports  of  the  Bolton  Operative 
Cotton-spinners'  Provincial  Association. 

2  See,   for  instance,   the  Local  Code  of  Rules  for  the  Guidance  of  Masons, 
signed  by  the  Central  Association  of  Master  Builders  of  London  and  the  Friendly 
Society  of  Operative  Stonemasons,  2$rd  June  1892. 

3  "  Pattern-makers,  millwrights,  and  machine  joiners  on  dismissal  must  receive 
two  hours'  notice,  so  as  to  grind  their  tools,  or  be  paid  two  hours  in  lieu  thereof." 
London  By-laws  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers,  April  1894,  clause  iv. 
Rule  vi.  p.  7. 


314  Trade  Union  Function 

day,  or  two  and  a  quarter  hours  extra  for  each  full  day  or  night, 
as  compensation  for  the  very  dirty  work."  ]  The  foregoing  are 
all  instances  of  "extras"  charged  by  Trade  Unions  of  time- 
workers.  But  we  find  a  similar  list  put  forward  by  Trade 
Unions  on  a  piecework  basis.  The  National  Union  of  Boot 
and  Shoe  Operatives  prescribes,  in  minute  and  technical 
detail,  for  a  long  list  of  extra  pieces  of  work,  to  be  specially 
paid  for.  And  a  large  part  of  the  length  and  complication 
of  the  well-known  "  scale  "  of  the  Compositors  is  due  to  their 
insistence  on  explicitly  defined  extra  rates  for  every  kind 
of  composition  involving  more  labor  than  "  common  matter." 
It  is  impossible  to  convey  any  adequate  idea  of  the  number 
and  variety  of  the  "  extras  "  thus  formally  agreed  to  between 
employers  and  employed :  "  bottom  notes,"  "  side  notes," 
"  under  runners,"  "  small  chases,"  "  large  pages,"  "  pamphlets," 
"  catalogues,"  "  undisplayed  broadsheets,"  "  table  work," 
"  column  work,"  "parallel  matter,"  "split  fractions,"  "superiors," 
"  inferiors,"  "  slip  matter,"  "  interlinear  matter,"  "  prefatory 
matter,"  "  indices,"  "  appendices,"  and  what  not.  Finally,  as 
if  to  discourage  vain  learning,  Hebrew,  Arabic,  and  Syriac, 
and  similar  languages,  together  with  "  pedigrees,"  are  "  to  be 
paid  double  the  price  of  common  matter."  2 

We  do  not  think  that,  after  so  long  and  detailed  an 
examination  of  the  Standard  Rate,  we  need  weary  the  reader 
by  any  lengthy  exposition  of  the  Trade  Union  regulations 
prohibiting  arbitrary  fines  and  deductions,  or  any  form  of 
"  truck."  It  may  seem  unreasonable  for  the  workmen  to 
object  to  the  employer's  system  of  maintaining  discipline  in 
the  factory.  But  if  that  system  takes  the  form  of  imposition 
of  fines  for  minor  offences,  and,  as  is  usually  the  case,  the 
employer  puts  the  fines  into  his  own  pocket,  it  is  clear  that 
the  average  amount  of  the  fines  per  week  is,  in  effect,  an 
exactly  proportionate  reduction  of  the  Standard  Rate.  An 
employer  using  this  method  of  enforcing  the  necessary 

1  Rule  VI.   of  By-laws  for  the  Mersey  District,   United  Society  of  Boiler- 
makers.     1889. 

2  The  London  Scale  of  Prices  for  Compositors'  Work.      1891. 


The  Standard  Rate  315 

discipline  finds  himself  buying  his  labor  cheaper  than  his 
competitors,  by  an  amount  varying  precisely  in  proportion 
to  the  frequency  and  severity  of  the  penalties  which  he  him- 
self imposes.1  The  same  arbitrary  character  attaches  to  the 
once  universal  system  of  making  the  operatives  pay  for  minor 
breakages,  or  for  incidental  requirements  of  their  work.  "  In 
the  good  old  times  of  low  wages,  irregular  work,  and  poor 
living,"  ironically  writes  an  official  of  the  Cotton-spinners, 
"operatives  used  to  have  to  pay  for  broken  bobbins,  gas, 
new  brushes,  find  their  own  oil-cans,  renew  parts  of  their 
machines  that  got  broken,  and  no  end  of  other  nice  little 
things  that  made  a  fair  hole  in  their  wages."  2  Against  all 
these  practices  the  Cotton-spinners  have  long  since  made 
good  their  protest.  The  Cotton- weavers,  of  whom  a  large 
majority  are  women,  are  still  occasionally  imposed  upon,  and 
the  rules  of  their  unions  accordingly  still  include  a  peremptory 
injunction  against  submitting  to  any  such  deductions.  "  Never 
pay,  or  agree  to  pay,"  say,  for  instance,  the  Preston  rules, 
"  for  any  shuttles,  forks,  brushes,  or  any  piece  of  machinery, 
matter,  or  thing  belonging  to  the  master,  or  used  in  his 
business  in  any  way  whatsoever,  except  what  you  may  have 
by  sheer  negligence  wilfully  or  maliciously  broken  or  de- 
stroyed ;  and  if  they  stop  it  from  your  wages,  bring  the  case 
before  the  Committee  at  their  next  meeting."  3  But  it  is  not 

1  A  system  of  fines  may  be  less  objectionable  if  the  money  goes  to  the 
operatives'  sick  club,  or  some  other  fund  for  their  common  benefit.     But  sick 
clubs  or  superannuation  funds  connected  with  particular  establishments,  especially 
if  membership  is  compulsory,  are  objectionable  from  the  Trade  Union  point  of 
view  on  other  grounds,  notably  that  of  diminishing  the  operative's  independence. 
This  subject  is  further  examined  in  the  chapter  on  "  The  Implications  of  Trade 
Unionism." 

2  Cotton  Factory  Times,  22nd  July  1892. 

3  Rules  of  the  Preston  and  District  Power  Loom  Weavers'  Association  (Preston, 
1891),  p.  20. 

In  piecework  trades,  the  employer  seeks  to  escape  paying  for  any  but  perfect 
articles,  and  usually  claims  the  right  to  reject,  without  appeal,  any  that  he  chooses. 
This  has  led  to  a  whole  series  of  conflicts  in  different  industries.  The  Trade 
Unionist  contention  has  been  ( I )  that  the  operative  should  not  be  made  to  suffer 
for  failures  due  to  the  imperfection  of  material,  or  defects  in  the  process  ;  (2)  that 
in  any  case,  if  the  employer  refuses  to  pay  anything  for  the  work  on  the  ground 
of  its  imperfection,  he  should  not  retain  the  article  for  his  own  profit,  but  destroy 


316  Trade  Union  Function 

only  such  arbitrary  charges  as  fines  and  deductions,  which 
necessarily  vary  from  mill  to  mill,  that  are  fundamentally 
inconsistent  with  the  collective  settlement  of  a  Standard 
Rate.  Even  such  uniform,  regular,  and  definite  payments 
as  the  "  loom  rent "  of  the  hand-working  weaver  of  cotton, 
silk,  or  carpets,  the  frame  rent  of  the  hosiery  worker,  and  the 
trough  or  wheel  rent  of  the  Sheffield  cutler,  have  been  found, 
by  long  and  painful  experience,  to  be  equally  destructive  of 
any  definite  standard  of  earnings.  This  arises  from  their 
being  continuous  and  calculated  by  time,  whilst  the  operative's 
work  is  irregular  and  paid  for  by  the  piece.  In  all  these 
cases  rent  of  the  machine  is  exacted  by  the  employer  whether 
the  operative  is  given  work  or  not.  Thus,  as  the  framework 
knitters  allege,  when  they  paid  rent  for  their  frames,  the 
employers  were  tempted  to  spin  out  the  work  over  much 
longer  periods  than  was  necessary,  doling  it  out  in  very  small 
portions  in  order  to  keep  them  paying  rent  as  long  as 

it ;  and  (3)  that  there  should  be  some  means  of  appeal  against  the  employer's 
arbitrary  judgment  in  his  own  cause.  Thus  the  Potters  have  fought  a  long  battle 
for  the  last  sixty  years  against  the  condition  termed  "good  from  oven,"  by  which 
the  workman  is  only  paid  for  such  articles  as  come  out  perfect  from  the  firing 
oven.  As  he  has  no  power  to  select  material,  and  no  control  over  the  firing  of 
the  oven,  this  condition  throws  upon  him  not  only  the  cost  of  his  own  negligence, 
but  also  that  due  to  imperfection  of  raw  material,  defects  of  fixed  plant,  and  care- 
lessness of  foremen  or  other  operatives.  It  is  a  further  aggravation  that  the 
employer  arbitrarily  decides  which  articles  should  be  rejected  as  imperfect,  and 
was  formerly  even  free  to  retain  and  sell  those  which  he  had  thus  escaped  paying 
for.  After  the  great  strike  of  1836  the  Staffordshire  Potters  succeeded  in 
remedying  the  latter  grievance.  It  was  agreed  that  articles  rejected  as  imperfect 
should  be  broken  up,  a  great  temptation  being  thus  removed  from  unscrupulous 
employers.  But  "  good  from  oven "  still  remains  the  basis  of  payment,  the 
Trade  Union  demand  of  "good  from  hand  "  being  still  resisted  by  the  employers. 
In  the  same  way  the  Glass  Bottle  Makers,  who  have  several  rules  in  their  agree- 
ments with  their  employers  defining  minutely  the  circumstances  under  which 
men  may  or  may  not  be  charged  for  spoiled  work,  have  one  declaring  "  that 
bottles  picked  out  (as  spoiled)  be  not  broken  down  until  the  men  have  had  an 
opportunity  of  inspecting  them,  but  in  no  case  shall  they  be  kept  beyond  the 
following  day."  Article  10  of  the  Agreement  for  1895  .  .  .  bet-ween  the  York- 
shire Glass  Bottle  Manufacturers'  Association,  and  the  Glass  Bottle  Makers  of 
Yorkshire  United  Trade  Protection  Society  (Castleford,  1895). 

A  particularly  aggravated  form  of  the  same  grievance  is  resisted  by  the 
Friendly  Society  of  Ironfounders,  whose  members  are  all  paid  by  time.  Not- 
withstanding this,  and  the  fact  that  they  neither  choose  the  raw  material  nor 
direct  the  process,  attempts  are  from  time  to  time  made  by  employers  to  make 
deductions  for  castings  which  turn  out  badly. 


The  Standard  Rate  3 1 7 

possible.  And  the  Macclesfield  silk-weavers  complain  that 
they  are  kept  always  half  employed,  the  giver-out  of  work 
rinding  his  advantage  in  getting  it  done  on  as  many  separate 
looms  as  possible,  from  each  of  which  a  full  weekly  rent  is 
derived.  It  is  easy  to  see  how  such  a  system  may  open  a 
way  for  personal  tyranny  and  exaction.  It  is  more  to  our 
immediate  purpose  to  notice  how  incompatible  it  is  with 
Collective  Bargaining  and  a  Standard  Rate.  If  the  employer 
can  give  out  work  in  unequal  quantities  to  different  operatives, 
but  deduct  from  each  an  equal  sum  at  the  end  of  the  week, 
no  fixed  piecework  list  will  secure  identical  pay  for  identical 
work.  If  A  is  given  thirty  pieces  to  weave,  and  B  only 
fifteen,  both  may  be  paid  at  the  same  rate  of  a  shilling  per 
piece,  and  both  may  pay  the  same  loom  rent  of  five  shillings 
per  week.  Yet  at  the  end  of  the  week, the  net  remuneration 
for  weaving  one  piece  will  have  been  to  A  tenpence  and  to 
B  eightpence.  Thus  the  rate  of  payment  for  identical  work 
will  vary  from  operative  to  operative,  from  week  to  week, 
and  even  from  firm  to  firm,  according  to  the  way  in  which, 
at  the  uncontrolled  discretion  of  the  employers,  the  work  is 
distributed.1  A  similar  objection  applies,  it  will  be  seen,  to 
the  whole  system  of  "  truck,"  or  the  compulsory  purchase  by 
the  operatives  of  commodities  or^rrratcrials  supplied  by  the 
employers.2  This  is  resisted  by  the  unions  on  the  larger 

1  Many  minor  payments  similar  in  principle  to  loom  rent  exist  in  various 
industries.      Where  the  operatives  are  unorganised,  and  especially  if  they  are 
women  or  girls,  employers  are  apt  to  attempt  to  charge  them  for  some  part  of  the 
manufacturing  process,  or  for  incidental  stores  or  material.      This  is  sometimes 
done  to  avoid  the  cost  and  trouble  of  proper  supervision  to  prevent  waste  and 
breakages.      In  other  cases  it  arises  as  an  incident  of  a  growing  specialisation  of 
function.     Thus,  cotton-weavers  used  to  oil  their  own  looms,  but  the  employers 
found   that    it  was    better    done    by  a    professional    oiler,   who    was    thereupon 
employed.     Any  attempt  to  deduct  even  a  penny  per  week  per  pair  of  looms  to 
pay  his  wages  is  peremptorily  stopped  by  the  Weavers'  union.      Similar  develop- 
ments of  specialisation  in   cotton-spinning  might  be  cited — the  uprise  of  the 
"  strap-piecer  "  and  the  "bobbin-carrier"  for  instance.     But  no  deduction  for 
their  wages  is  permitted  by  the  Cotton-spinners'  unions  (Cotton  Factory  Times, 
loth  June  1892).     Women  woollen  weavers  are,  however,  still  made  to  pay  the 
"tuner"  of  their  looms,  his  work  of  "setting  "  the  warp  and  weft  being  done  by 
the  male  weavers  for  themselves. 

2  The  Miners'  Conference  in  1863  made  this  a  special  subject  of  complaint. 
1 « The  truck  system  still  prevails  in  Scotland  and  Wales,  despite  of  both  equity 


318  Trade  Union  Function 

ground  that  it  amounts  to  an  insidious  enslavement  of  the 
wage-earner  and  his  family.  But  it  is  also  inconsistent  with 
any  uniformity  in  the  net  rate  at  which  employers  obtain 
their  labor,  and  with  definite  standard  of  real  income  of  the 
wage-earner  under  such  a  system,  notwithstanding  a  nominal 
uniformity  of  rate,  both  labor  cost  and  real  wages  will  vary 
according  to  the  extent  of  the  truck  business  in  each  firm, 
the  economy  and  ability  with  which  this  subsidiary  store- 
keeping  is  managed,  and  the  profit  or  "  loading"  which  each 
employer  chooses  to  exact,  the  latter  amounting,  in  effect,  to 
a  fraud  upon  the  workman.1 

We  see,  therefore,  that  the  adoption  of  a  Standard  Rate 
— that  is,  of  payment  for  labor  according  to  some  definite 
standard,  uniform  in  its  application — is  not  by  any  means 
so  simple  a  matter  as  would  at  first  sight  appear.  Whether 
we  accept  payment  by  the  hour  or  payment  by  the  piece, 
so  great  are  the  complications  of  modern  industry,  and  so 
ingenious  are  the  devices  for  evasion,  that  a  long  series  of 
subsidiary  regulations  is  found  necessary  to  defend  the  main 
position.  The  whole  argument  for  this  series  of  subsidiary 

and  law.  That  no  man  should  be  forced,  as  a  condition  of  work,  to  spend  his 
money  on  necessaries  for  the  benefit  of  his  employer  is  both  law  and  reason.  In 
Scotland  .  .  .  the  men  are  only  paid  by  the  fortnight,  the  month,  or  longer ; 
and  in  the  interim  tickets  for  food  or  clothing  are  furnished,  by  which,  at  certain 
shops,  articles  are  furnished  at  an  enormous  overcharge  above  a  fair  market 
average  of  cost.  In  some  cases  the  poor  collier  rarely  sees  current  coin,  all  being 
forestalled  betwixt  the  term  of  pay  and  work.  .  .  .  Allied  to  this,  in  Stafford- 
shire and  elsewhere,  the  butties  and  doggies,  or  middlemen,  still  continue  to 
influence  and  compel  the  colliers  to  spend  part  of  their  wages  in  drink,  as  a 
condition  of  employment.  In  other  cases,  in  Yorkshire,  candles  and  powder 
must  be  purchased  of  the  steward,  or  some  other  man,  at  exorbitant  prices  above 
the  market  rate  of  profit." — 7"ransactions  and  Results  of  the  National  Association 
of  Coal i  Lime,  and  Ironstone  Miners  of  Great  Britain  (London,  1863),  p.  xi. 

These  practices  have  now  been  stopped  by  the  miners'  unions  in  all  well- 
organised  districts.  Similar  grievances  are,  however,  still  complained  of  in  some 
other  trades,  where  the  operatives  are  powerless  to  insist  on  the  Truck  Acts  being 
obeyed  in  spirit  as  well  as  in  the  letter. 

1  "  Wherever  the  workmen  are  paid  in  goods,  or  are  compelled  to  purchase 
at  the  master's  shop,  the  evils  are  very  great ;  much  injustice  is  done  to  the  men, 
and  much  misery  results  from  it.  Whatever  may  have  been  the  intentions  of  the 
master  in  such  a  case,  the  real  effect  is  to  deceive  the  -workman  as  to  the  amount 
he  receives  in  exchange  for  his  labor" — On  the  Economy  of  Machinery  and 
Manufactures,  by  Charles  Babbage  (London,  1832),  p.  255. 


The  Standard  Rate  319 

regulations  rests,  it  is  clear,  upon  the  principal  contention. 
It    seems,    therefore,    worth    while    to    rehearse    the    Trade 
Unionist's  argument.      We  have  seen  that  it  is  a  fundamental 
article  of  the  Trade  Union  faith  that  it  is  impossible,  in  a 
system  of  competitive  industry,  to  prevent  the  degradation 
of  the  Standard  of  Life,  unless  the  conditions  of  labor  are 
ittled,  not  by  Individual  Bargaining,  but  by  some  Common 
Lule.     But,  without  the  uniform  application  of  some  common 
standard,  collective  settlement  of  these  conditions,  whether 
by  bargain,  arbitration,  or  law,  is  plainly  impossible.1     Where 
employer  is  competing  with  employer,  each  will  claim  that, 
if  he  must  forego  the  chances  of  Individual   Bargaining,  he 
should  at  any  rate  be  made  to  pay  no  more  for  his  labor 
lan  his  rivals.      With  this  contention  the  Trade   Unionist 
icartily  agrees,  and  thus  we  get  admitted,  as  the  basis  of  the 
Common   Rule,  the  principle  of  identical  pay  for  identical 
iffort,  or,  as  it  is  usually  termed,  the  Standard   Rate.     This, 
we  have  seen,  is  the  very  opposite  to  equality  of  wages. 
[ow  accurately  this  principle  of  identical  pay  for  identical 
fort  can  be  applied  to  the  varying  capacities  of  different 
workmen,  or  to  the  varying  difficulties  of  particular  tasks, 
whether    it    can    be    most    precisely   carried    into  effect    by 
payment  by  time  or  payment  by  the  piece,  depends  upon  the 
character  of  the  process  and  the  intelligence  and  integrity  of 
the  parties.     But  it  is  obviously  futile  to  settle,  by  collective 
regulation  of  any  kind,  a  Standard  Rate  of  identical  pay  for 
identical  effort,  if  an  unscrupulous  employer  is  free  to  evade 
this  by  demanding  extra  work  or  additional  wear  and  tear ; 
by  deducting  anything  from  the  wage  agreed  upon  ;  or  by 

1  The  dependence  of  combination  among  workmen  upon  the  existence  of  a 
Standard  Rate  was  well  expressed,  from  the  employer's  point  of  view,  by 
Alexander  Galloway,  the  well-known  engineer,  and  friend  to  Francis  Place.  "I 
have  always  found  that  in  those  employments  where  the  wages  were  uniform  .... 
there  have  always  been  combinations  among  those  men.  Now  in  all  those  trades 
where  the  men  have  made  their  own  individual  engagements,  we  never  see  any- 
thing like  combinations.  .  .  .  That  which  has  struck  most  effectually  at  the 
root  of  all  combination  among  workmen  is  to  pay  every  man  according  to  his 
merit,  and  to  allow  him  to  make  his  own  agreement  with  his  employer." — Evidence 
in  First  Report  of  Committee  on  Artisans  and  Machinery^  1824,  p.  27. 


320  Trade  Union  Function 

obtaining,  at  the  cost  of  his  workmen,  by  any  transaction 
with  them,  any  other  monetary  advantage  whatever.  In 
short,  if  the  fundamental  object  of  Trade  Unionism,  the 
enforcement  of  a  Common  Rule,  has  any  justification  at  all, 
the  principle  of  the  Standard  Rate  must  be  conceded,  and 
if  a  Standard  Rate  is  admitted,  the  subsidiary  regulations 
which  we  have  described  follow  as  a  matter  of  course. 

This  general  conclusion  in  favor  of  a  Standard  Rate- 
a  point  on  which  every  Trade  Unionist  would  unhesitatingly 
agree — leaves  many  questions  with  regard  to  wages  unsettled. 
One  of  these  is,  on  what  principle,  and  to  what  extent,  the 
Standard  Rate  should,  in  the  same  industry,  vary  from  town  to 
town.  The  employers  in  the  out-of-the-way  districts  are  apt 
to  contend  that  the  workman  must  put  up  with  a  low  rate, 
because  of  the  inferiority  of  their  machinery,  their  heavy 
charges  for  freight,  and  other  local  disadvantages.  But  there 
seems  no  reason  why  the  workman  should  lower  his  standard 
of  life,  and  forego  his  claim  to  identical  pay  for  identical 
effort,  merely  because  the  capitalist  chooses  to  carry  on  his 
business  amid  unprofitable  surroundings.  Whether  Trade 
Unionists  should  go  in  for  equality  of  nominal  wages  (a 
uniform  national  standard  rate),  or,  making  allowance  for 
difference  in  the  cost  of  living,  claim  only  equality  of  real 
wages  (involving  varying  local  rates),  has  never  been  settled 
in  principle.  There  are  obvious  practical  difficulties  in 
carrying  out  the  latter  idea,  as  it  is  impossible  to  measure 
with  any  precision  differences  in  the  cost  of  living  in  different 
districts.  Accordingly  we  find  most  of  the  "  county  "  unions, 
especially  those  of  the  cotton  operatives  and  coalminers, 
aiming  at  a  uniform  county  rate,  irrespective  of  local  circum- 
stances. Similarly,  the  strong  old  union  of  hand  paper- 
makers,  working  entirely  in  a  few  small  provincial  towns, 
easily  maintains  a  uniform  rate  for  the  whole  industry.1  But 

1  A  uniform  Standard  Rate  is  said  to  have  formed  one  of  the  principal  demands 
of  the  great  French  strike  of  1791,  which  extended  to  many  trades  and  to  all 
parts  of  France  (Du  Cellier,  Histoire  des  Classes  Laborieuses  en  France,  pp.  320- 
322  ;  Decree  of  the  National  Assembly  of  I4th  June  1791). 


The  Standard  Rate  32  i 

directly  the  cost  of  living  becomes  appreciably  different,  even 
the  strongest  unions  admit  variations  in  local  rates.  The 
Journeymen  Hatters'  Fair  Trade  Union  of  Great  Britain  and 
Ireland,  the  old-established  society  of  silk  hat  makers,  has  a 
uniform  price  list,  but  allows  its  London  branch  to  add  10 
per  cent  to  the  general  rates.  When  we  come  to  the  larger 
and  more  widely  distributed  unions,  we  see  the  widest 
possible  divergence.  Thus  the  631  branches  of  the  Amal- 
gamated Society  of  Carpenters  in  Great  Britain  and  Ireland 
recognise  no  fewer  than  twenty  rates,  varying  from  5d.  per 
hour  in  Truro  to  lod.  per  hour  in  London.  Here,  as  in 
many  other  cases,  we  may  well  doubt  whether  even  equality 
of  real  wages  has  been  attained.  Not  only  has  there  been 
no  attempt  by  any  large  union  to  secure  a  national  uniform 
rate,  but  there  is  a  tendency  for  officers  and  executive 
committees  to  be  apathetic  with  regard  to  the  process  of 
"  levelling  up,"  which  would  be  necessary  to  obtain  equality 
of  real  wages.  The  result  is  that  Trade  Unionism  cannot  be 
said  yet  to  have  progressed  beyond  the  securing  of  a  local 
Standard  Rate.  This  leaves  the  workmen  exposed  to  the 
constant  attempts  of  employers  to  "  level  down  "  the  rates  in 
the  better-paid  districts,  in  order,  as  they  assert,  to  meet  the 
competition  of  the  lower -paid  districts.  Our  own  idea  is 
that  the  assumed  differences  in  the  cost  of  living,  taking  one 
thing  with  another,  resolve  themselves  practically  into  differ- 
ences in  the  rent  of  a  workman's  dwelling.  The  expedient  of 
the  Hatters  seems,  therefore,  the  most  practical  thing  to  aim  at. 
There  would  be  many  advantages  in  the  enforcement  of  a 
uniform  Standard  Rate  in  all  districts  of  an  industry,  treating 
all  provincial  towns  and  urban  districts  on  an  equality,  but 
adding  a  percentage  for  the  exceptional  high  rents  payable 
in  London,  and,  if  necessary,  deducting  a  percentage  in 
respect  of  the  very  low  rents  in  a  purely  agricultural  district, 
in  the  cases  in  which,  as  in  the  building  trades,  the  industry 
comprises  both  town  and  country.  These  percentages  could 
be  calculated  on  easily  ascertained  and  undisputed  facts.1 

1  Instead  of  a  uniform  Standard  Rate  for  all  the  establishments  in  each  town 
VOL.  I  Y 


322  Trade  Union  Function 

A  more  obvious  problem  with  regard  to  wages  must  be 
deferred  to  a  subsequent  chapter.  We  can  imagine  that  the 
reader  has  had  in  his  mind  an  uneasy  feeling  that  we  are 
evading  what  he  conceives  to  be  the  crucial  point,  namely, 
the  share  of  the  joint  product  to  be  allotted  for  the  remunera- 
tion of  the  manual  labor.  But  the  Trade  Union  Regulation 
with  which  we  are  dealing — the  insistence  on  a  Standard 
Rate — is  not  an  end  but  a  means  :  not  any  particular  sum 
of  money  per  week,  but  a  device  for  obtaining  for  the  whole 
body  of  competitors  something  better  than  they  would 
get  by  Individual  Bargaining.  Thus  the  Sheffield  Fork- 
grinders,  the  Dock  Laborers,  the  Engineers,  and  the  Steel 
Smelters  all  insist  on  the  Standard  Rate.  But  if  we  look  at 
the  weekly  earnings  for  which  each  trade  is  righting,  we  find 

or  district,  we  occasionally  find  attempts  to  enforce  two  or  three  different  rates  for 
what  are  assumed  to  be  different  grades  of  work.  Thus  the  Scottish  Tailors 
recognise  in  many  towns  two,  and  in  Glasgow  and  Edinburgh  three  classes  of 
shops,  those  requiring  a  better  quality  of  tailoring  being  compelled  to  pay  a  half- 
penny or  even  a  penny  per  hour  more  than  the  lowest  Trade  Union  rate.  The 
custom  is  for  the  employers  to  classify  themselves,  the  union  objecting  if  any 
attempt  is  made,  for  instance,  to  get  "  dress  goods  "  (superfine  black  broadcloth) 
made  at  the  second-class  rate,  or  (in  Edinburgh  and  Glasgow)  "tweeds"  at  the 
third  class.  In  so  far  as  these  different  rates  correspond  to  real  and  ascertainable 
differences  in  the  class  of  work,  they  are,  it  is  clear,  not  inconsistent  with  the 
principle  of  a  uniform  Standard  Rate.  In  some  cases,  however,  the  different 
rates  depend  more  on  the  custom  and  tradition  of  the  various  shops  than  upon  any 
definite  difference  in  the  work  done.  Thus  the  London  branch  of  the  National 
Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  has  long  recognised  three  different 
"  Statements,"  applying  respectively  to  firms  deemed  first,  second,  or  third  class. 
An  establishment  which  has  hitherto  paid  the  first-class  "  Statement "  is  not 
allowed  to  do  any  work  at  a  lower  "Statement,"  for  fear  this  should  lead 
insidiously  to  the  reduction  of  the  rates  of  the  first-class  men.  On  the  other  hand, 
there  is  nothing  to  prevent  a  firm,  hitherto  classed  as  third  or  second  class,  from 
making  at  these  lower  rates  goods  nearly  identical  with  those  usually  produced  at 
the  first-class  "Statement."  The  result  is  that  the  first-class  firms  are  always 
finding  themselves  undersold  (or  at  any  rate,  believing  themselves  to  be  under- 
sold) by  enterprising  firms  on  the  second-class  statement.  The  employers  and 
the  experienced  officials  of  the  union  have,  for  ten  years,  been  urging  the 
abolition  of  these  separate  "  Statements,"  and  the  preparation  of  the  uniform  list 
for  all  London  firms,  with  carefully  gradated  piecework  rates  for  every  kind  of 
boot.  Hitherto  all  attempts  at  uniformity  have  broken  down,  owing  mainly  to 
the  rooted  belief  of  the  union  that  no  reduction  of  existing  rates  ought  anywhere 
to  be  conceded.  As  a  consequence,  the  first-class  employers  are  said  to  find  a 
constantly  increasing  difficulty  in  maintaining  their  position  in  London.  The 
controversy  can  be  best  followed  in  the  Shoe  and  Leather  Record  for  the  last  ten 
years. 


The  Standard  Rate  323 

this  varying  from  twenty-four  shillings  a  week  up  to  three 
times  that  amount.  One  thing  will  be  clear,  even  to  the 
most  superficial  observer.  There  is,  in  the  Trade  Union 
world  of  to-day,  absolutely  no  trace  of  any  desire  for 
equality  of  wages.  The  cardroom  operatives  in  a  Lanca- 
shire Cotton  mill,  earning  from  ten  to  twenty  shillings  a 
week,  will  unhesitatingly  come  out  on  strike  to  assist  the 
cotton-spinners  to  maintain  a  Standard  Rate,  paid  out  of 
the  products  of  the  combined  labor  of  the  two  sections, 
averaging  forty  shillings  a  week.  The  local  federations  of 
the  building  trades,  whose  members  work  side  by  side 
at  the  same  job,  collectively  insist,  in  their  treaties 
with  the  employers,  on  half  a  dozen  different  rates  per 
hour  for  the  different  crafts,  the  Stonemason  habitually 
getting  fifty  per  cent  more  than  the  Builders'  Laborciv-aad 
the  rates,  in  the  present  generation,  showing  no  tendency 
to  approximate.  Unanimity  of  Trade  Union  policy 
does  not,  in  fact,  extend  beyond  the  use  of  a  common 
device.  How  much  money  each  trade  will  claim,  no  less 
than  how  much  each  will  actually  receive,  depends,  in 
practice,  on  the  traditions,  customs,  and  present  opportunities 
of  the  particular  trade  and  section  concerned.  The  ex- 
pectations and  aspirations  of  the  operatives,  the  arguments 
adduced  in  justification  of  their  demands,  and,  to  some 
extent,  the  particular  Trade  Union  Method  employed 
to  enforce  them,  will,  as  we  shall  show  in  our  chapter  on 
the  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism,  depend  principally 
on  the  Doctrine  or  Doctrines  as  to  social  expediency  by 
which  the  policy  of  the  particular  union  is,  for  the  time 
being,  directed. 


CHAPTER    VI 

THE    NORMAL    DAY 

AFTER  the  Standard  Rate,  the  most  universal  of  the  Trade 
Union  Regulations  is  what  we  have  termed  the  Normal 
Day,  the  determination  of  a  uniform  maximum  working 
time  for  all  the  members  of  a  craft.1  This  claim  to  fix  the 
limits  of  the  working  day  is  peculiar  to  the  manual-working 
wage -earner.  Corporations  of  lawyers,  doctors,  architects, 
and  other  professional  brainworkers  insist,  with  more  or  less 
stringency,  on  scales  of  minimum  fees,  below  which  no 
practitioner  is  allowed  to  undertake  work.  But  the  con- 
ception of  a  precise  Common  Rule  as  to  the  hours  during 
which  an  individual  shall  work  is  foreign  both  to  the  pro- 

1  By  the  term  "Normal  Day"  we  mean  the  "maximum  working  day"  of 
Schaffle  {Theory  and  Practice  of  Labour  Protection,  London,  1893)  and 
Frankenstein  (Der  Arbeiterschtitz,  Leipzig,  1896),  not  the  elaborately  equated 
"normal  day"  of  Rodbertus  (Der  Normalarbeitstag,  Berlin,  1871),  varying 
according  to  the  assumed  intensity  of  labor  in  different  occupations.  The  latter 
academic  conception  has  never  penetrated  to  the  minds  either  of  English  Trade 
Unionists  or  German  Social  Democrats. 

From  the  economic  standpoint  there  has  been  as  yet  little  scientific  investi- 
gation of  the  results  of  fixing  the  maximum  working  day.  The  Eight  Hotirs 
Day,  by  Sidney  Webb  and  Harold  Cox  (London,  1891),  and  E.  L.  Jaeger's 
Geschichte  und  Literatur  des  Normalarbeittages  (Stuttgart,  1892)  give  the 
principal  references,  to  which  may  now  be  added  Hadfield  and  Gibbins'  A 
Shorter  Working  Day  (London,  1892) ;  C.  Deneus,  La  Journte  de  Huit 
Heures  (Ghent,  1893);  H.  Stephan,  Der  Normalarbeitstag  (Leipzig,  1893); 
Professor  L.  Brentano's  Ueber  das  Verhaltniss  von  Arbeitslohn  und  Arbeit szeit 
zur  Arbeitsleistung  (Leipzig,  1893),  translated  as  Hours  and  Wages  in  Relation 
to  Production  (London,  1894);  Jonn  Rae>  Eight  Hours  for  Work  (London, 
1894)  ;  and  Maurice  Ansiaux,  Heures  de  Travail  et  Salaires  (Paris,  1896). 


The  Normal  Day  325 

pertied  and  to  the  brain-working  class.  Nor  has  it  always 
characterised  the  wage -earners.  The  trade  clubs  of  the 
eighteenth  century  claimed  a  legal  rate  of  wages,  or  a  standard 
list  of  prices,  they  insisted  on  a  limitation  of  apprentices,  or 
sought  to  enforce  the  Elizabethan  Statutes  ;  but  not  until 
the  close  of  the  century  do  we  find  any  widespread  com- 
plaints of  the  length  or  irregularity  of  the  working  day. 
From  the  beginning  of  the  present  century  the  demand  for 
a  deliberately  fixed  limit  of  hours  for  each  day's  work,  to 
be  arranged  either  by  Collective  Bargaining  or  by  Legal 
Enactment,  has  spread  from  one  occupation  to  another, 
until  to-day  the  great  majority  of  the  Trade  Unions  make 
the  regulation  of  working  hours  one  of  their  foremost  objects. 
Nevertheless,  there  exist  even  to-day  small  sections  of  the 
working  class  world  who  resist  any  Common  Rule  as  to 
their  hours,  and  prefer  that  each  individual  should  be  free  to 
labor  when  and  for  as  long  as  he  may  choose.  We  have, 
therefore,  to  seek  some  explanation,  not  only  of  the  present 
popularity  of  the  idea  of  a  Normal  Day,  but  also  of  its 
comparatively  modern  growth,  and  of  its  rejection  by  certain 
sections  of  Trade  Unionists. 

In  modern  industry  the  settlement  of  the  hours  of  labor 
differs  in  an  essential  particular  from  that  of  the  rate  of 
payment  for  the  work  done.  In  the  absence  of  any  form 
of  collective  regulation,  the  rates  of  wages  are  determined 
by  Individual  Bargaining  between  the  capitalist  employer 
and  his  several  "  hands " ;  and  a  distinct  and  varying 
agreement  as  to  the  amount  of  remuneration  is  made  with 
each  operative  in  turn.  This  is  seldom  the  case  with 
regard  to  the  length  and  distribution  of  the  working  day. 
In  all  the  numerous  industries  in  which  work  is  not  done 
on  the  employer's  premises,  but  is  still  "  given  out "  to  be 
done  at  home,  the  manual  worker,  paid  "  by  the  piece,"  is  as 
free  as  the  author,  doctor,  or  conveyancer,  to  fix  the  number 
of  hours,  and  the  exact  part  of  the  day  or  week  or  year, 
that  he  chooses  to  spend  in  labor.  He  has,  of  course,  like 
the  professional  man,  to  suit  the  convenience  of  his  clients. 


326  Trade  Union  Function 

He  must  be  on  the  spot  to  receive  work  when  it  comes,  and 
he  must  finish  it  by  the  time  it  is  required.  He  must  be 
willing  to  do  extra  work  in  the  busy  season,  and  even  to 
turn  night  into  day  to  cope  with  a  special  rush  of  orders. 
But  subject  to  this  condition,  each  man  can  settle  for  him- 
self the  exact  hours  at  which  he  will  begin  his  work,  and  the 
intervals  he  will  allow  himself  for  meals  and  rest.  Unless  he 
is  driven,  by  reason  of  the  low  rate  at  which  he  is  paid,  to 
work  "all  the  hours  God  made"  in  order  to  get  bare 
subsistence,  he  may  break  off  when  he  likes  to  gossip  with 
a  friend  or  slip  round  to  the  public-house  ;  he  may,  in  the 
intervals,  nurse  a  sick  wife  or  child ;  and  he  can  even 
arrange  to  spend  the  morning  in  his  garden,  or  doing  odd 
jobs  about  the  house.  No  one  acquainted  with  the  daily 
life  of  the  home-working,  skilled  craftsman,  earning  "  good 
money,"  will  ignore  the  large  use  that  such  a  man  makes  of 
his  freedom.  For  good  or  for  evil  his  working  hours  are 
determined  by  his  own  idiosyncrasies.  Whether  he  desires 
to  earn  much,  or  is  content  with  little  ;  whether  he  is  a  slow 
worker  or  a  quick  one  ;  whether  he  is  a  precise  and  punctual 
person  governing  himself  and  his  family  by  rigid  rules,  or 
whether  he  is  "  endowed  with  an  artistic  temperament," 
and  needs  to  recover  on  Monday  and  Tuesday  from  the 
"expansion"  of  the  preceding  days — these  personal  character- 
istics will  determine  the  limits  and  distribution  of  his  working 
time.1 

1  The  injurious  effect  upon  the  personal  character  of  the  "  average  sensual 
man"  of  this  freedom  to  stop  working  whenever  he  feels  inclined,  is  referred  to 
in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism."  The  axiom  that  the 
vast  majority  of  the  manual  workers,  like  other  men,  are  the  better  for  a  certain 
degree  of  discipline,  would  not  find  ready  acceptance  among  the  rank  and  file  of 
Trade  Unionists,  and,  therefore,  can  hardly  be  given  as  a  Trade  Union  argument 
in  favor  of  a  Normal  Day.  But  the  more  thoughtful  workmen  would  concur 
with  the  dictum  of  an  early  admirer  of  the  factory  system,  that  when  operatives 
were  "  obliged  to  be  more  regular  in  their  attendance  at  their  work,  they  became 
more  orderly  in  their  conduct,  spent  less  time  at  the  ale-house,  and  lived  better 
at  "home "  (Memoirs  of  the  Manchester  Literary  and  Philosophical  Society, 
Second  series,  London,  1819,  vol.  iii.  p.  129,  in  a  paper  "On  the  Rise  and 
Progress  of  the  Cotton  Trade,"  read  in  1815  by  John  Kennedy).  "I  always 
observed,"  wrote  an  old  compositor  in  1859,  "  that  those  trades  who  had  settled 
wages,  such  as  masons,  wrights,  painters,  etc.,  and  who  were  obliged  to  attend 


The  Normal  Day  327 

Very  different  is  the  position  of  the  factory  operative, 
Instead  of  each  individual  being  able  to  work  as  he  chooses, 
the  whole  establishment  finds  itself,  by  the  nature  of  things, 
subject  to  a  Common  Rule.  In  a  textile  mill,  a  coal  mine,  a 
shipbuilding  yard,  an  engineering  firm,  or  a  great  building 
operation  it  is  economically  impossible  to  permit  the  individual 
workman  to  come  or  go  as  he  feels  inclined.  Each  worker 
forms  part  of  a  complex  co-operative  process,  needing  for  its 
proper  fulfilment  an  exact  dovetailing  of  the  task  of  every 
machine  and  every  "  hand  "  in  the  work  as  a  whole.  To 
arrange  particular  hours  of  labor  to  suit  the  varying 
desires,  capacities,  and  needs  of  the  different  operatives, 
would  be  obviously  incompatible  with  the  economical  use 
of  steam  power,  the  full  employment  of  plant,  or  the  highly 
organised  specialisation  brought  about  by  division  of  labor. 
There  is  no  longer  a  choice  between  idiosyncrasy  and  uni- 
formity. A  common  standard,  compulsory  in  its  application, 
is  economically  inevitable.  The  only  question  is  how  and 
by  whom  the  uniform  rule  shall  be  determined.  In  the 
absence  of  collective  regulation,  whether  in  the  form  of  Legal 
Enactment  or  Collective  Bargaining,  this  uniform  rule  is 
naturally  made  by  the  employer.1  And  it  is  a  special 
aggravation  of  this  subordination,  that,  under  the  circum- 
stances of  the  modern  capitalist  industry,  the  employer's 
decision  will  perpetually  be  biassed  in  favor  of  lengthening 
the  working  day.  With  regard  to  his  domestic  servants, 
the  capitalist  is  free  to  determine  the  amount  of  toil  solely 
with  a  view  of  keeping  them  in  the  highest  possible  efficiency. 
But  the  same  man  investing  capital  in  expensive  machines, 
worked  by  power,  finds,  even  when  he  pays  by  the  piece,  a 

regularly  at  stated  hours,  were  not  so  much  addicted  to  day  drinking  as  printers, 
bookbinders,  tailors,  shoemakers,  and  those  tradesmen  who  generally  were  on 
piecework,  and  not  so  much  restricted  in  regard  to  their  attendance  at  work  except 
when  it  was  particularly  wanted." — Scottish  Typographical  Circular,  March 
1859. 

1  "  It  should  always  be  remembered,"  remark  the  Cotton-spinners  in  1860 
"  that  anterior  to  the  introduction  of  factory  legislation,  the  employers  dictated 
the  hours  of  labor  to  their  work-people." — Rides  of  the  Amalgamated  Association 
of  Operative  Cotton- spinners,  edition  of  1860,  preface. 


328  Trade  Union  Function 

positive  profit  in  every  additional  moment  that  his  costly 
plant  is  being  employed.  Competition  is  always  forcing 
him  to  cut  down  the  cost  of  production  to  the  lowest 
possible  point.  Under  this  pressure  other  considerations 
disappear  in  the  passion  to  obtain  the  greatest  possible 
"  output  per  machine."  ] 

Between  these  two  historic  types  of  the  domestic  handi- 
craftsman and  the  factory  operative,  there  are  various 
intermediate  forms  in  which  Individual  Bargaining  as  to  the 
hours  of  labor  is  as  possible  as  Individual  Bargaining  with 
regard  to  the  rate  of  payment.  In  occupations  such  as 
agriculture,  and  even  in  special  departments  of  the  great 
industries,  it  is  at  any  rate  practicable  for  an  employer  to 
vary  the  hours  of  his  several  workpeople,  or,  in  other  words, 
to  make,  if  he  likes,  a  bargain  with  each  according  to  his 
capacity,  just  as  the  ordinary  capitalist  claims  to  be  allowed 
to  pay  each  man  "  according  to  his  merit."  Where  this  is 
the  case,  the  workman's  need  for  a  Normal  Day  depends 
on  considerations  strictly  analogous  to  those  which  cause 
him  to  need  a  Standard  Rate.  If  each  workman  is  free  to 
conclude  what  bargain  he  chooses  with  regard  to  his  working 
hours,  the  employer  will,  it  is  contended,  be  able  to  use  the 
desires  or  exigencies  of  particular  individuals  as  a  means  of 
compelling  all  the  others  to  accept  the  same  longer  working 
day. 

So  far  we  have  considered  the  Trade  Union  demand  for 
a  Normal  Day  only  in  relation  to  the  personal  freedom  of 
the  operative  to  take  such  leisure  as  he  may  deem  necessary 

1  "The  great  proportion  of  fixed  to  circulating  capital  .  .  .  makes  long 
hours  of  work  desirable.  .  .  .  The  motives  to  long  hours  of  work  will  become 
greater,  as  the  only  means  by  which  a  large  proportion  of  fixed  capital  can 
be  made  profitable.  When  a  laborer,"  said  Mr.  Ashworth  to  me,  "lays 
down  his  spade,  he  renders  useless  for  that  period  a  capital  worth  eighteenpence. 
When  one  of  our  people  leaves  the  mill,  he  renders  useless  a  capital  that  has 
cost  ^100." —  Nassau  Senior,  Letters  on  the  Factory  Act  (London,  1837), 
pp.  11-14. 

"  Hence  that  remarkable  phenomenon  in  the  history  of  modern  industry,  that 
machinery  sweeps  away  every  moral  and  natural  restriction  on  the  length  of  the 
working  day."  —  Marx,  Capital^  Part  iv.  ch.  xv.  sec.  3  (vol.  ii.  p.  406  of 
English  Translation  of  1887). 


The  Normal  Day  329 

or  desirable.  But  to  the  Trade  Unionist,  as  to  the  rank  and 
file  of  the  manual  working  class,  the  length  of  the  day's  work 
and  the  amount  left  over  for  leisure  is  of  secondary  import- 
ance beside  the  vital  question  of  the  sum  earned.  Keen  as 
is  the  average  workman  to  secure  more  time  to  himself,  he 
is  far  keener  to  obtain  more  money  to  spend.  In  all  time- 
work  trades  in  which  Trade  Unionism  exists  the  operative 
gets  extra  pay  for  extra  hours,  usually  at  a  higher  rate, 
whilst  the  whole  race  of  pieceworkers  obviously  increase 
their  earnings  by  working  overtime.1  Every  progressive 
lengthening  of  the  working  day  would  therefore  seem  to 
bring  with  it,  as  a  compensating  advantage,  a  corresponding 
increase  in  the  weekly  income  of  the  wage-earner.2 

1  In  certain  unorganised  occupations  men,  and  especially  women,  are  still 
required  to  work  longer  hours  to  cope  with  a  press  of  orders  without  getting  any 
additional  payment  for  the  extra  labor.      But  this  is  seldom  the  case  in  trades  in 
which  there  is  any  kind  of  organisation. 

2  This  is  exactly  how  it  appears  to  the  well-to-do  literary  man.     Thus,  Mr. 
Lecky  is  much  concerned  at  the  diminution  of  earnings  which  he  supposes  to 
be  caused    by  the    Factoiy  Acts.      "  Take,   for  example,  the  common   case  of 
a    strong    girl    who    is    engaged    in    millinery.       For,     perhaps,    nine    months 
of    the  year   her   life    is    one    of   constant    struggle,    anxiety,    and    disappoint- 
ment,    owing    to    the    slackness    of    her    work.      At    last    the    season    comes 
bringing    with    it   an    abundant  harvest   of  work,  which,   if  she   were  allowed 
to    reap  it,    would    enable    her    in    a  few   weeks  to    pay    off  the    little    debts 
which   weigh   so  heavily  upon  her,  and  to  save  enough  to   relieve  her  from  all 
anxiety  in  the  ensuing  year.     She  desires  passionately  to  avail   herself  of  her 
opportunity.      She  knows  that  a  few  weeks  of  toil  prolonged  far  into  the  night 
will  be  well  within  her  strength,  and  not  more  really  injurious  than  the  long 
succession  of  nights  that  are  spent  in  the  ball-room  by  the  London  beauty  whom 
she  dresses.      But  the  law  interposes,  forbids  her  to  work  beyond  the  stated  hours, 
dashes  the  cup  from  her  thirsty  lips,  and  reduces  her  to  the  same  old  round  of 
poverty  and  debt.     What  oppression  of  the  poor  can  be  more  real  and  more 
galling  than  this?" — Democracy  and  Liberty  (London,  1896),  vol.  ii.  p.  342. 

It  is  interesting  to  contrast  with  this  imaginary  instance  the  reports  of  the 
responsible  women  officials  who  are  in  actual  contact  with  facts,  and  conversant 
with  the  views  of  the  operatives.  Writing  in  1894,  Miss  May  Abraham  (the 
Senior  Woman  Factory  Inspector)  reports  that  "  by  dressmakers  and  milliners  .  . . 
legal  overtime  is  almost  universally  condemned.  A  dressmaker's  assistant,  whose 
legal  working  day  had,  for  a  considerable  period,  lasted  from  8  A.M.  to  10  P.M., 
said  to  me  in  the  presence  of  her  fellow- workers,  '  The  overtime  exception  just 
spoils  the  Factory  Act.'  The  chorus  of  approval  with  which  her  remark  was 
endorsed  was  a  clear  indication  of  general  discontent,  and  further  experience 
showed  that  this  had  been  but  one  expression  of  an  almost  universal  feeling.  .  .  . 
In  factories  where  the  payment  is  by  piecework,  or  in  some  districts,  as  in 
Dublin,  where  a  stipulated  sum  is  allowed  for  overtime,  the  weight  of  hostile 


330  Trade  Union  Function 

Now,  if  Trade  Unionists  believed  that  this  apparent 
result  was  the  real  result, — that  freedom  to  work  longer  hours 
invariably,  or  even  usually,  meant  a  corresponding  increase 
of  income, — we  doubt  whether  there  would  have  arisen  any 
general  movement  in  favor  of  limiting  the  hours  of  labor. 
But,  rightly  or  wrongly,  Trade  Unionists  are  convinced  that 
irregular  or  unlimited  hours  have  an  insidious  influence  upon 
wages,  first  upon  the  Standard  Rate  and  ultimately  upon 
the  amount  earned  by  each  man  per  week. 

This  conviction  springs  from  the  personal  experience  of 
the  manual  working  wage-earner.  At  any  Trade  Union 
meeting  where  the  hours  of  labor  are  discussed,  it  may 
happen  that  a  young  and  energetic  member  will  suggest 
that  he  would  prefer  a  larger  income  to  increased  leisure. 
But  one  old  member  after  another  will  get  up  and  explain 
that  as  a  young  married  man  he  had  felt  the  same,  but  that 
experience  of  workshop  life  had  taught  him  that  "  what  was 
gained  in  hours  was  lost  in  rates  " — an  assertion  which  finds 
immediate  and  unhesitating  confirmation  from  the  bulk  of 
the  meeting.  If  after  the  meeting  the  visitor  argues  the 
point  with  the  leading  men,  and  suggests  that  their  personal 
experience  may  not  warrant  so  large  a  generalisation  as  that 
a  lengthening  of  hours  will  necessarily  lead  to  a  reduction 
of  the  rate  of  payment  per  hour  or  per  piece,  they  will 
retort  by  asking,  why  it  is  that  Royal  Commissions  and 
official  statistics  are  always  laying  bare  this  almost  universal 
coincidence  between  long  and  irregular  hours,  low  rates  of 
pay,  and  small  weekly  earnings.  Nor  will  they  fail  to  give 
an  explanation,  based  on  actual  experience.  "  Our  members," 

opinion  is  not  so  pronounced  ;  but  even  here,  with  the  inducement  of  a  supple- 
mentary wage,  it  is  only  the  most  unthinking  of  the  workers  who  favor  the 
system.  .  .  .  The  consequent  effect  on  the  health  of  the  workers  is  exceedingly 
injurious  ...  I  believe  .  .  .  that  by  the, workers  [the  abolition  of  all  over- 
time] would  be  welcomed  with  feelings  of  the  warmest  gratitude"  (Report  of  (he 
Chief  Inspector  of  Factories  for  1893,  c-  736^  of  1894,  p.  11).  This  and  other 
reports  contain  abundant  confirmation  of  Miss  Abraham's  view.  "Could  a 
secret  ballot  be  taken,"  says  Mr.  Cramp,  one  of  the  Superintending  Inspectors, 
"  of  all  the  workers  affected  by  the  overtime  clauses  of  the  Factory  and  Workshop 
Acts,  I  am  convinced  that  very  few  would  be  found  voting  for  its  continuance." 
— Ibid.  p.  299. 


The  Normal  Day  331 

they  will  say,  "  look  on  thirty  shillings  as  a  fair  week's  wage. 
If  they  make  it,  they  are  content ;  if  they  don't  make  thirty 
shillings,  they  come  to  the  branch  and  complain.  When 
a  master  increases  the  hours,  say  from  fifty-four  to  sixty,  it 
seems  at  first  a  clear  gain  to  the  men,  who  make  more  money. 
Presently,  on  some  excuse,  the  foreman  announces  a  ten  per 
cent  cut  in  rates.  The  men  grumble,  but  as  most  of  them 
will  still  make  thirty  shillings  a  week,  they  put  up  with  a 
reduction  against  which  they  would  certainly  have  come  out, 
if  it  had  meant  their  only  making  twenty-seven  shillings. 
After  a  time  the  weaker  men  find  they  can't  keep  up  their 
output  for  such  long  hours.  In  a  few  months,  the  average 
weekly  earnings  of  the  shop  will  have  dropped,  and  the  men 
will  be  wearing  themselves  out  for  even  less  money  at  the 
end  of  the  week  than  they  had  before.  Again  and  again 
we  have  seen  this  happen,  and  no  amount  of  middle-class 
theory  will  make  us  believe  it  is  not  so." 

The  Trade  Union  official  who  has  read  his  economic  text- 
book will  put  the  argument  in  more  systematic  form.  When 
an  employer  engages  a  laborer  at  so  much  a  week,  the 
length  of  the  working  day  clearly  forms  an  integral  part  of 
the  wage-contract.  A  workman  who  agrees  to  work  longer 
time  for  the  same  money  underbids  his  fellows  just  as 
surely  as  if  he  offered  to  work  the  same  time  for  less  money. 
He  sells  each  hour's  work  at  a  lower  rate.  Among  all  time- 
workers,  therefore,  who  are  paid  by  the  day,  week,  or  month, 
the  insistence  on  a  Normal  Day  is  a  necessary  element  in 
the  maintenance  of  their  Standard  Rate. 

Where  piecework  prevails,  or  where  the  time-worker  is 
paid  by  the  hour,  the  case  is,  to  the  Trade  Unionist,  no  less 
clear.  At  first  sight  it  would  seem  that  liberty  to  work  for 
longer  hours  leaves  the  Standard  Rate  unaffected,  whilst  it 
increases  the  amount  of  the  weekly  earnings  of  industrious 
men.  This  seems  so  obvious  to  the  middle-class  mind  that 
employers  have  for  generations  been  honestly  unable  to 
understand  why  a  pieceworking  Trade  Union  should  concern 
itself  about  the  hours  of  labor  at  all.  According  to  the 


33 2  Trade  Union  Function 

Trade  Unionists,  this  is  to  ignore  the  plain  teaching  of 
economics,  as  well  as  the  experience  of  practical  men.  To 
them  it  seems  obvious  that  the  actual  earnings  of  any  class 
of  workers  are  largely  determined  by  its  Standard  of  Com- 
fort, that  is  to  say,  the  kind  and  amount  of  food,  clothing, 
and  other  commodities  to  which  the  class  has  become  firmly 
accustomed.1  It  would  not  be  easy  to  persuade  an  English 
engineer  to  work  at  his  trade  for  thirteen  shillings  a  week, 
however  excessive  might  be  the  supply  of  engineers.  Rather 
than  do  such  violence  to  his  own  self-respect,  he  would  work 
as  a  laborer,  or  even  sweep  a  crossing.  On  the  other  hand, 
however  much  in  request  a  Dorsetshire  laborer  might  find 
himself  it  would  not  enter  into  his  head  to  ask  two  pounds  a 
week  for  his  work.  There  is,  in  fact,  the  Trade  Unionist 
asserts,  in  each  occupation  a  customary  standard  of  livelihood, 
which  is,  within  a  specific  range  of  variation,  tacitly  recognised 
by  both  employers  and  employed.  Upon  this  customary 
standard  of  weekly  earnings,  the  piecework  or  hour  rates 
are,  more  or  less  consciously,  always  based.2  If  there  is  no 
limit  to  the  number  of  hours  that  each  man  may  work  or  the 
employer  may  require,  some  exceptionally  strong  men,  able, 
if  only  for  a  few  years,  to  work  unceasingly  from  morning 
till  night,  will  earn  an  income  far  beyond  the  customary 
standard  of  their  class.  In  any  bargaining  about  the  Piece- 
work List  these  large  earnings  will  be  quoted  by  the  employer 
as  typical  of  what  every  workman  might  do  if  only  he  were 
industrious,  and  will  be  urged  as  grounds  why  a  reduction 

1  This  assumption — that  the  rate  of  wages  of  any  race  or  class  of  wage-earners 
is  largely  determined  by  the  standard  of  expenditure — enunciated  by  Adam  Smith 
and  generally  accepted  by  later  economists,  will  be  further  examined  in  our 
chapter  on  "  The  Higgling  of  the  Market  "  ;  and  the  argument  that  the  bulwark 
against  competitive  pressure  afforded  by  this  instinctive  Standard  of  Life  is 
enormously  strengthened  by  the  Methods  and  Regulations  of  Trade  Unionism, 
will  be  elaborately  analysed  in  the  chapter  on  "The  Economic  Characteristics  of 
Trade  Unionism." 

55  "A  price  list  has  always  implicitly  (and  as  will  be  seen  sometimes  explicitly) 
a  time-basis,  i.e.  it  is  generally  understood  that  the  piece-rates  agreed  on  are  such 
as  to  enable  the  average  worker  with  average  exertion  to  earn  a  certain  weekly 
wage." — Board  of  Trade  (Labor  Department)  Report  on  Wages  and  Hours  oj 
Labour  Part  II.>  Standard  Piece  Rates,  C.  7567. — I.  1894,  p.  vii. 


The  Normal  Day  333 

in  the  rate  is  only  reasonable.1  Nor  is  this  merely  a  ques- 
tion of  successful  argument.  The  exceptional  men  them- 
selves will  not  be  inclined  to  hazard,  by  any  dispute,  what 
is  to  them  ample  livelihood,  and  will  oppose  any  attempt 
on  the  part  of  the  Union  to  resist  reductions  or  apply  for 
advances.  The  hours  thus  exceptionally  worked  tend,  there- 
fore, insidiously  to  become  customary  for  the  whole  trade, 
and  the  piecework  rates  are  gradually  lowered  so  as  to  yield, 
on  the  longer  hours,  a  weekly  income  corresponding  to  the 
standard  of  expenditure  to  which  the  class  is  accustomed. 
The  ultimate  result  upon  the  Standard  Rate  of  leaving  the 
hours  of  labor  unlimited  is  accordingly  the  same  in  the  case 
of  payment  by  the  piece  or  hour  as  it  is  in  the  case  of  pay- 
ment by  the  day  or  week.  If,  as  the  Trade  Unionists  con- 
tend, unrestrained  competition  among  the  individual  operatives 
tends  to  lengthen  the  working  day  for  all  alike,  it  also  insidi- 
ously lowers  the  rate  of  remuneration  for  the  work  done. 
The  men  who  have  started  longer  hours  gradually  find 
themselves  earning  no  more  than  they  had  formerly  done  in 
the  customary  day,  whilst  all  the  rest  discover  that  they  can 
only  maintain  their  old  wages  by  similarly  increasing  their 
working  time.  Thus  the  whole  class  gives  in  return  for  its 
customary  livelihood  increased  labor  and  energy,  involving 
greater  wear  and  tear,  and  the  weaker  members,  unable  to 
keep  up  the  strain,  are  forced  down  to  a  lower  level  of  sub- 
sistence. The  same  arguments,  therefore,  which  lead  the 
Trade  Unionist  to  insist  on  a  definite  Standard  Rate,  impel 
him,  quite  apart  from  any  advantage  to  be  gained  from 
increased  leisure  and  irrespective  of  the  system  under  which 
he  is  paid,  vigorously  to  uphold  the  Normal  Day.2 

1  See  the  instances  cited  by  the  Shipwrights  and  Coopers  in  the  subsequent 
note. 

2  It  might,  indeed,  be  urged  that  the  Trade  Unionist  argument  in  favor  of 
collective  regulation  of  the  hours  of  labor,  considered  merely  as  a  means  of  keeping 
up  the  price  at  which  the  wage-earner  sells  each  unit  of  energy,  has  a  broader 
psychological  basis  than  the  argument  for  a  Standard  Rate  itself.      If  it  be  true, 
as  is  always  asserted  both  by  employers  and  by  Trade  Union  officials,  that  the 
individual  manual  worker  is  far  keener  to  maintain  and  add  to  his  income  than 
to  preserve  or  increase  his  leisure,  it  seems  to  follow  that  a  Trade  Union  which 


334  Trade  Union  Function 

The  Trade  Unionist  position  with  regard  to  the  Normal 
Day  is  therefore  extremely  complicated.  So  long  as  we  fix 
our  attention  solely  on  the  proportion  between  work  and 
leisure,  the  wage-earners  fall,  as  we  have  seen,  into  three 
classes.  To  the  "  hands  "  employed  in  a  co-operative  process, 
involving  the  use  of  costly  plant  and  machinery,  and  carried 
on  upon  a  large  scale,  the  fixing  of  a  Normal  Day  appears 
the  only  alternative  to  leaving  their  working  hours  to  be 
determined,  and  in  all  probability  gradually  lengthened, 
according  to  the  autocratic  judgment  of  their  employer.  To 
the  domestic  handicraftsman,  on  the  other  hand,  working  in 
his  own  garret,  any  collective  regulation  of  the  hours  of  work 
is  a  distinct  curtailment  of  his  personal  liberty,  an  evil  in 
itself  requiring  considerable  justification  before  he  will  be 
persuaded  to  adopt  it.  For  the  workmen  in  the  intermediate 
class  of  industries,  in  which  the  length  and  distribution  of 
the  working  day  can  practically  vary  from  individual  to 
individual,  the  question  will  depend  partly  on  the  extent  to 
which  hours  of  leisure  offer  any  attraction  to  them,  and  partly 
upon  the  degree  to  which  they  realise  the  perils  of  Individual 
Bargaining.  Assuming  the  Trade  Unionist  position  that  the 
wage-earners  can  obtain  better  conditions  by  collective  action, 
all  the  workmen  in  the  industries  standing  between  the 
domestic  handicraft  and  the  factory  system,  who  desire  to 
protect  or  increase  the  amount  of  their  leisure,  will  naturally 
come  more  and  more  to  insist  on  a  Normal  Day  as  a  neces- 
sary condition  of  this  collective  action.  But  this  simple 
classification  by  no  means  disposes  of  all  the  variations. 
With  all  classes  of  workers  a  second  and  usually  more  potent 
consideration  enters  into  the  argument,  namely,  the  result  of 
irregular  or  unlimited  hours  of  labor  upon  the  weekly  earn- 
ings. To  the  time-worker  paid  by  the  day,  week,  or  month, 
the  Normal  Day  is  obviously  a  part  of  his  bargain  for  a 

insisted  on  a  rigid  limitation  of  working  time  whilst  leaving  the  rate  of  pay  to  the 
chances  of  Individual  Bargaining,  would,  in  the  end,  secure  for  its  members  a 
higher  level  of  remuneration  for  a  given  expenditure  of  energy,  than  a  Trade 
Union  which  insisted  on  a  Standard  Rate,  but  left  the  length  and  intensity  of  the 
day's  labor  to  individual  agreements. 


The  Normal  Day  335 

Standard  Rate.  The  worker  by  the  piece  or  by  the  hour 
will  be  more  or  less  disposed  to  insist  on  Common  Rules 
fixing  working  time,  in  the  degree  that  the  circumstances  of 
his  industry  and  his  personal  observations  convince  him  that 
unregulated  hours  of  labor  tend  to  lower  the  rate  of  remunera- 
tion of  the  whole  class.1 

This  elucidation  of  the  Trade  Union  argument  gives  us 
the  necessary  clue  both  to  the  historical  development  of  the 
Hours'  Movement  and  to  its  present  position  in  the  Trade 
Union  world.  During  the  eighteenth  century  the  predomi- 
nant type  of  Trade  Unionist  was  the  handicraftsman  working 
as  an  individual  producer.  The  weavers  and  frame -work 
knitters,  whose  combinations  to  enforce  a  Standard  Rate 
date  from  the  very  beginning  of  that  century,  worked  in  their 
own  homes.  Out  -  work  prevailed,  too,  alongside  of  the 
employers'  workshop  in  many  other  of  the  organised  trades, 
such  as  the  shoemakers,  cutlers,  woolcombers,  and  hatters. 
And  even  where  workshop  industry  was  the  rule  the  familiar 
relations  between  the  master  workman  and  the  journeymen, 
the  absence  of  machinery  and  motive  power,  and  the  general 
slackness  of  discipline  enabled  the  members  of  such  trade 
clubs  as  the  sailmakers,  coopers,  curriers,  and  calico  block- 
printers  to  put  in  attendance  at  irregular  intervals.  This 
practical  freedom  to  leave  off  at  any  particular  moment, 
though  it  was  not  incompatible  with  what  we  should  now 
consider  excessive  hours  of  toil,  gave  the  operative  a  sense  of 
personal  liberty  which  naturally  disinclined  him  to  suggest 
any  collective  regulation  of  his  working  day.  Eighteenth- 
century  attempts  to  impose  a  Common  Rule  fixing  the  hours 

1  It  will  be  needless  to  remind  the  historical  student  of  the  numerous  gild 
ordinances  by  which  the  independent  master  craftsmen  of  the  Middle  Ages,  though 
individually  at  liberty  to  leave  off  when  they  chose,  deliberately  sought  to  fix  the 
maximum  hours  of  labor  of  each  trade,  mainly  in  order,  as  we  think,  to  prevent 
the  working  time  being  insidiously  lengthened,  and  the  standard  rate  of  payment 
undermined,  by  unfettered  competition.  Thus  the  Spurriers,  in  1345,  fix  the 
maximum  working  day  from  dawn  to  curfew  ;  the  Hatters,  Pewterers,  and  many 
others  in  the  fourteenth  century  prohibit  night- work  ;  and  the  Girdlers,  in  1344, 
forbid  work  "after  none  has  been  wrung"  on  Saturdays  or  festival  eves.— 
Memorials  of  London  and  London  Life,  by  H.  T.  Riley  (London,  1 868). 


336  'Irade  Union  Function 

of  labor  for  all  the  members  of  a  craft  are  accordingly  con- 
fined to  operatives  paid  by  the  day  or  week,  and  working  on 
the  premises  of  their  employers.  Thus,  the  establishment  of 
a  maximum  day  of  fourteen  hours  (less  meal-times)  was  a 
leading  demand  of  that  combination  of  "  the  Journeyman 
Taylors  in  and  about  the  Cities  of  London  and  Westminster," 
which  we  have  cited  as  one  of  the  earliest  Trade  Unions.  "  'Tis 
certain,"  runs  the  workmen's  petition,  "  that  to  work  fifteen 
hours  per  day  is  destructive  to  the  men's  health,  and  especially 
their  sight,  so  that  at  forty  years  old  a  man  is  not  capable 
by  his  work  to  get  his  bread."  And  from  the  masters' 
petition  we  learn  that  the  men  "  insist  upon  and  have  twelve 
shillings  and  ninepence  per  week  (instead  of  ten  shillings  and 
ninepence  per  week,  the  usual  wages),  and  leave  off  work  at 
eight  of  the  clock  of  night  (instead  of  nine,  their  usual  hour, 
time  out  of  mind)."1  And  turning  to  other  trades,  it  is 
significant  that  while  there  is,  during  the  whole  of  the 
eighteenth  century,  no  trace  of  any  hours'  movement  among 
the  pieceworking  coopers  of  London,  the  day-working  coopers 
of  Aberdeen  are  found,  as  early  as  1732,  "  entering  into 
signed  associations  among  themselves,  whereby  they  become 
bound  to  one  another  under  a  penalty  not  to  continue  in  their 
masters'  service,  or  to  work  after  seven  o'clock  at  night, 
contrary  to  the  usual  practice."2  The  only  other  cases  of 
eighteenth-century  movements  that  we  know  of  for  regular 
or  shorter  hours  occurred  among  the  saddlers  and  bookbinders 

1  An  Abstract  of  the  Master  Taylors    Bill  before   the   Honourable  House 
of   Commons;    with   the  Journeymen's    Observations    on    each    Clause   of  the 
said  Bill  (London,  1720).      Similar  movements  are  recorded  among  the  tailors 
of  Aberdeen  in   1720  and    1768   (Bain's  Merchant  and  Craft   Gilds,  p.  261), 
and  those  of  Sheffield  in   1720   (Sheffield  Iris,    8th  August  1820).      See,   for 
all  these  instances,  the  interesting  collection  of  original  Documents  Illustrating 
the   History   of  Trade    Unionism,  No.    I.    The   Tailoring  Trade,    by    F.    W. 
Gallon,   published  by  the  London   School  of  Economics  and  Political  Science 
(London,  1896). 

2  Bain's  Merchant  and  Craft  Gilds  of  Aberdeen,  p.  246.     A  similar  distinction 
may  be  drawn  between  the  pieceworking  hatters,  who  continued  to  work  unlimited 
hours  in  their  own  homes,  and  the  London  hat-finishers,  who,  working  by  time 
on  the  employers'  premises,  struck  in  1777  for  a  reduction  of  hours. — House  of 
Commons  Journals,  vol.  xxxvii.  p.  192  (i8th  February  1777)- 


The  Normal  Day  337 

in  the  last  years  of  the  century,1  who  at  that  time  worked 
by  the  day  and  were  in  the  employers'  workshops. 

The  isolated  and  exceptional  cases  of  the  tailors,  hat- 
finishers,  saddlers,  and  bookbinders  emphasise  the  general 
indifference  relating  to  the  hours  of  labor  which  marks 
eighteenth-century  Trade  Unionism.2  This  indifference  was 
not  wholly  due  to  the  greater  laxity  with  regard  to  hours 
and  workshop  discipline  possible  under  a  system  of  individual 
production.  For  the  protection  of  their  Standard  Rate  the 
eighteenth -century  handicraftsmen  were  able  to  resort  to 
methods  no  longer  open  to  the  modern  Trade  Unionist.  The 
clubs  of  town  artisans  sought  to  protect  their  position  by  the 
stringent  enforcement  of  the  laws  requiring  a  seven  years' 
apprenticeship,  and  imposing  a  limit  on  the  number  of  persons 
learning  the  craft.  The  home-working  weavers  petitioned 
Parliament,  in  some  cases  successfully,  for  the  legal  enforce- 
ment of  their  customary  rates  of  payment.  The  position  of 
the  eighteenth-century  Trade  Unionist  was  in  many  respects 
analogous  to  that  of  the  modern  solicitor  or  doctor,  who, 
maintaining  his  Standard  Rate  by  high  educational  tests 
and  the  exclusion  of  unauthorised  competitors,  is  unable  to 
understand  what  justification  can  be  urged  for  the  imposition 
of  a  uniform  Normal  Day. 

Very  different  is  the  record  of  the  nineteenth  century. 
With  the  introduction  of  machinery  moved  by  power,  and 
the  rapid  development  of  the  factory  system,  the  operatives 
in  the  new  textile  industries  lost  all  individual  control  over 
their  working  day.  "  Whilst  the  engine  runs,"  wrote  an 
,  acute  observer  of  the  new  industry,  "  the  people  must  work. 
Men,  women,  and  children  are  yoked  together  with  iron  and 
steam.  The  animal  machine — breakable  in  the  best  case, 

1  See  the  Saddlers'  "Addresses,"  preserved  in  the  Place  MSS.,  27,799-112, 
114;  and  Dunning's  "Account  of  the  London  Consolidated  Society  of  Book- 
binders, "  in  the  Social  Science  Association  Report  on  Trade  Societies  and  Strikes, 

*    1860,  p.  93. 

2  Adam  Smith,  as  Marx  pointed  out,  habitually  treated  the  working-day  as  a 
constant  quantity. — Capital,   Part   IV.  ch.  xix.  (vol.  ii.  p.  552  of  English  trans- 
lation of  1887). 

VOL.  I  7. 


338  Trade  Union  Function 

subject  to  a  thousand  causes  of  suffering,  changeable  every 
moment — is  chained  fast  to  the  iron  machine,  which  knows 
no  suffering  and  no  weariness."  Accordingly  we  find  the 
combinations  of  the  Cotton-spinners,  from  the  very  begin- 
ning of  their  history,  eagerly  supporting  the  efforts  of  phil- 
anthropists to  obtain  from  Parliament  a  legal  regulation 
of  the  hours  of  Jabor.  The  successive  Factory  Acts  thus 
obtained  applied  in  terms,  it  is  true,  only  to  women  and 
children.  But  it  was  obvious  to  contemporary  observers  that 
the  whole  strength  of  the  agitation  came  from  the  men's 
desire  for  a  legal  restriction  of  their  own  working  day.1  In 
1867  the  leaders  of  the  Lancashire  Cotton-spinners'  unions 
summoned  a  delegate  meeting  expressly  "  to  agitate  for  such 
a  measure  of  legislative  restriction  as  shall  secure  a  uniform 
Eight  Hours'  Bill  in  factories,  exclusive  of  meal -times,  for 
adults,  females,  and  young  persons  ;  and  that  such  Eight 
Hours'  Bill  have  for  its  foundation  a  restriction  on  the  moving 
power."  2  It  was,  however,  impossible  to  induce  the  Parlia- 
ment of  these  years  even  to  listen  to  the  idea  of  a  direct 
legal  limitation  of  the  hours  of  adult  male  workers ;  and 
when,  in  1872-74,  the  Lancashire  operatives  successfully 
agitated  for  a  further  reduction  of  the  working  day,  they  were 
astute  enough  to  couch  their  demand  in  terms  of  a  mere 
amendment  to  the  Ten  Hours'  Act  of  1847.  Twenty  years 
later  we  find  the  recognised  organ  of  the  same  union  declar- 
ing that  "  now  the  veil  must  be  lifted  and  the  agitation 
carried  on  under  its  true  colours.  Women  and  children 
must  no  longer  be  made  the  pretext  for  securing  a  reduction 
of  working  hours  for  men.  The  latter  must  speak  out  and 
declare  that  both  they  and  the  women  and  children  require 

1  Thus,  R.  H.  Greg,  citing  the  Report  of  the  Royal  Commission  on  Factories, 
vol.  i.  p.  47  of  1837,  observes  :   "It  is  obvious,  therefore,  that  the  condition  of 
children  has  been  only  the  cloak  for  an  ulterior  object,  which  object  is  now 
frankly  avowed  to  be  the  same  for  which  the  agitation  of  1833  took  place,  namely, 
the  attainment  of  the  Ten  Hours'  Bill,  or  a  Bill  for  preventing  any  factory  from 
working  more  than  ten  hours  in  any  one  day. " —  The  Factory  Question  Considered 
in  Relation  to  its  Effects  on  the  Health  and  Morals  of  those  employed  in  Factories, 
etc.  (London,  1837),  p.  17. 

2  Beehive^  23rd  February  1867  ;  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  p.  295. 


The  Normal  Day  339 

less  hours  of  labor  in  order  to  share  in  the  benefits  arising 
from  the  improvements  in  productive  machinery.  The  work- 
ing hours  cannot  be  permanently  reduced  by  Trade  Union 
effort.  ...  It  is  only  by  the  aid  of  Parliament  that  work- 
ing hours  can  be  made  somewhat  uniform." 1  In  another 
great  industry  the  operatives  had  found  themselves  equally 
at  the  mercy  of  their  employer's  decision  as  to  the  working 
day.  The  coalminers,  working  underground,  can  descend 
and  ascend  only  when  the  mine  manager  chooses  to  leave 
the  shaft  free  from  coal-drawing,  and  set  the  men's  cage  in 
motion.  Hence  the  coalminers,  as  soon  as  they  were  effectively 
organised,  began  to  agitate  for  a  fixed  working  day.  Already 
in  1844-47  we  find  Martin  Jude,  the  miners'  leader,  making 
"an  Eight  Hours'  Bill"  one  of  the  foremost  objects  of  the 
Miners'  Association  of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland,  which  in 
those  years  covered  all  the  English  coalfields.  From  1863 
to  1 88 1  it  was,  as  we  have  described,2  an  important  plank 
in  the  programme  of  Alexander  Macdonald.  Finally,  in 
1885  we  find  the  Lancashire  Miners'  unions  expressly 
insisting  that  the  legal  limit  should  apply  to  men  and 
boys  alike — a  demand  which  was  quickly  taken  up  by  all 
the  miners'  unions  except  those  of  Northumberland  and 
Durham.8 

Meanwhile  the  transformation  of  the  building  and 
engineering  industries  was  causing  the  clubs  of  artisans  and 
mechanics  to  insist  on  a  definite  limit  to  the  working  day 
also  in  these  trades.  The  growth  of  large  machine-making 
establishments,  and  the  coming  in  of  the  general  "  con- 
tractor" for  building  operations,  both  dating  from  the  first 
quarter  of  the  present  century,  resulted  in  the  supersession 
of  the  small  working  master,  and  the  massing  together  of 
large  numbers  of  workmen,  using  expensive  machinery  and 
plant,  and  co-operating  under  strict  discipline  in  a  single 
undertaking.  In  the  great  upheaval  of  the  Building  Trades 
in  1833-34,  the  prohibition  of  overtime  appears  as  one  of 

1   Cotton  Factory  Times,  26th  May  1893. 
"  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  284-289.  3  Ibid.  pp.  378,  379. 


340  Trade  Union  Function 

the  men's  demands,  and  the  Builders'  Laborers,  in  particular, 
insisted  on  extra  pay  for  working  beyond  their  regular  hours 
on  Saturdays.1  In  1836  we  discover  the  London  Engineers 
engaged  in  an  eight  months'  struggle  with  their  employers  for 
the  establishment  by  mutual  agreement  of  a  definite  Normal 
Day  for  the  whole  trade  ;  a  struggle  which  ended  in  the 
fixing  of  a  Sixty  Hours'  week,  and,  for  the  first  time  in  the 
engineering  trade,  the  penalising  of  overtime  by  extra  rates. 
Before  this  strike,  though  the  day's  work  was  nominally  ten 
and  a  half  hours,  the  constant  prevalence  of  overtime,  without 
any  extra  rate  of  payment,  gave  the  men  no  protection  what- 
ever against  the  systematic  lengthening  of  hours  by  any 
individual  employer.2  How  soon  the  building  operatives 
secured  the  same  hours  is  not  recorded,  but  already  in  1846 
we  find  the  Liverpool  Stonemasons  demanding  a  Nine 
Hours'  Day.  From  this  time  forward  the  records  of  both  the 
engineering  and  building  Trade  Unions  show  the  movement 
for  the  more  strict  observance  and  progressive  shortening 
of  the  Normal  Day  to  have  been  continued  without  inter- 
mission. The  elaborate  treaty  concluded  in  1892  between 
the  London  Building  Trade  Unions  and  the  associated 
Master  Builders,  by  which  the  working  time  for  all  building 
work  within  twelve  miles  of  Charing  Cross  was  fixed  for 

1  See  the  Masters'  Address,  I2th  June  1833,  in  An  Impartial  Statement  of 
the  proceedings  of  the  members  of  the  Trades  Union  Societies  and  of  the  steps  taken 
in  consequence  by  the  Master  Tradesmen  of  Liverpool  (Liverpool,  1833).      Also 
the   Statement  of  the  Master  Builders  of  the  Metropolis  in  explanation  of  the 
differences  betiveen  them  and  the  -workmen  respecting  the  Trades  Unions  (London, 
1834).      It  may  be   mentioned  that  the  minute  books  of  the  Glasgow  Joiners, 
whose  secretary  was  a  leading  Owenite,  contain,  between  1833  and  1836,  frequent 
regulations  intended  to  secure  the  Normal  Day.     At  the  general  meeting  in  March 
1833,   for   instance,    they   formally  adopted  the   working  rules   of  the   Scottish 
National   Union,   which  penalised  overtime  by  "time  and  a  half"   rates.      In 
1836    we  find  the  Society,    after  a  successful  strike,   insisting,   not  only  on   a 
standard  wage  of  2os.   a  week,  but  also  on  the  total  prohibition  of  overtime  for 
that  season.     From  1834  onward  they  were  waging  constant  war  on  the  practice 
of  working  by  artificial  light,  securing  its  prohibition  in   1836  after  a  prolonged 
strike. 

2  Article  by  Mr.  John  Burnett  in  the  Newcastle  Weekly  Chronicle,  3rd  July 
1875  ;  Paper  read  by  William  Newton  on  behalf  of  the  Executive  of  the  Amal- 
gamated  Society  of  Engineers   at   the  Dublin  Meeting   of  the   Social  Science 
Association,  1861. 


The  Normal  Day  34 1 

every  week  in  the  year,  with  extra  rates  intended  to  penalise 
all  overtime,  is  only  one  of  the  latest  of  a  practically  unbroken 
series  of  collective  agreements. 

But  though  the  conception  of  a  Common  Rule  as  to  the 
hours  of  labor  has  now  spread  to  all  classes  of  Trade 
Unionists,  whether  paid  by  time  or  by  the  piece,  handi- 
craftsmen or  factory  operatives,  there  is,  among  the  different 
trades,  a  marked  difference  in  the  intensity  with  which  the 
demand  is  pressed  upon  the  employers  and  the  public.  Here 
again  our  analysis  of  the  Trade  Union  argument  helps  us  to 
understand  the  facts.  The  Cotton  Operatives  and  Coal- 
miners  are  the  most  strenuous  advocates  of  definitely  limited 
and  uniform  hours  of  labor.  This  is  not  surprising  when 
we  remember  that,  in  both  these  industries,  the  beginning 
and  leaving  off  of  work  depends,  not  on  the  will  of  the 
operative  but  on  the  starting  and  stopping  of  the  engine ; 
when  we  realise  further  that  in  both  cases  the  trades  are 
"  open "  to  all  comers,  and  that  the  Standard  Rate  is  pro- 
tected neither  by  the  Limitation  of  Apprentices  nor  the 
exclusion  of  laborers  from  other  occupations.  The  engineer- 
ing and  building  operatives  follow  at  some  distance  the 
textile  operatives  and  miners  in  demanding  a  strictly  defined 
working  day.  Almost  invariably  paid  by  time,  they  have 
recognised  that  some  collective  agreement  as  to  the  hours  of 
work  is  a  necessary  part  of  their  bargain  for  the  sale  of  their 
labor.1  But  the  economic  necessity  for  uniform  hours  is 

1  We  are  able  to  watch  the  growth  of  the  conception  of  the  Normal  Day  in 
some  of  the  handicrafts  gradually  passing  into  the  system  of  capitalist  establish- 
ments carried  on  upon  a  large  scale.  Thus,  the  Provident  Union  of  Shipwrights 
of  the  Port  of  London,  an  old  trade  club  which  emerged  into  publicity  when  the 
Combination  Laws  were  repealed,  resolved,  on  the  4th  of  October  1824,  "that  every 
member  of  this  Union  will  not  engross  a  greater  share  of  work  than  what  he  can 
accomplish  by  working  regular  hours,  viz.  :  not  before  six  o'clock  in  the  morning, 
nor  later  than  six  in  the  summer  evening  ;  and  that  no  candle  work  be  performed 
after  the  people  on  the  outside  have  left  work,  so  that  every  opportunity  may  be 
given  to  those  out  of  employ."  And  it  is  instructive  to  notice  that  the  men's 
main  reason  for  this  innovation  was  declared  to  be  ''that  it  was  necessary  to 
regulate  a  day's  work  in  consequence  of  the  masters  stating,  when  a  man  had 
worked  for  fourteen  or  sixteen  hours,  that  they  earned  IDS.  per  day,  although 
there  was  one-half  as  regarded  the  number  of  hours."  The  same  motive  shortly 
afterwards  impelled  the  London  Coopers,  who  are  pieceworkers,  to  make  a 


342  Trade  Union  Function 

with  them  neither  so  obvious  nor  so  absolute  as  in  the  mine 
or  the  cotton-mill ;  and  in  both  these  industries  the  unions 
have  relied,  for  the  protection  of  their  Standard  Rates,  on 
their  traditional  policy  of  insisting  on  a  period  of  apprentice- 
ship, limiting  the  number  of  boys,  and  excluding  "  illegal  men." 
With  the  disuse  of  apprenticeship,  and  the  impracticability 
of  maintaining  a  policy  of  exclusion,  the  engineering  and 
building  Trade  Unions  are  insisting,  with  ever -increasing 
urgency,  on  the  rigid  enforcement  of  a  definitely  limited 
Normal  Day.  Where,  on  the  other  hand,  the  unions  still 
rely  for  the  defence  of  their  Standard  Rate  upon  such 
apprenticeship  regulations  as  are  enforced  by  the  United 
Society  of  Boilermakers,  and,  less  universally,  by  the  various 
unions  of  Compositors,  their  policy  with  regard  to  the  Normal 
Day  is  more  uncertain.  In  both  these  trades,  as  we  have 
seen,  timework  and  piecework  are  equally  recognised  by  the 
union.  In  both  cases  the  union  unhesitatingly  insists  on  a 
definite  Normal  Day  for  all  work  paid  for  by  time.  But 
owing  to  the  existence  of  other  defences  of  the  Standard 
Rate,  and  of  the  practical  freedom  of  these  hand  workers  to 
arrange  their  own  rate  of  speed,  and  the  details  of  their 
working  time,  their  faith  in  any  uniform  Normal  Day  for 
pieceworkers  partakes  rather  of  the  nature  of  a  pious 
opinion. 

With  archaic  trades  this  lukewarmness  passes  into  in- 
difference, if  not  even  hostility.  The  most  important,  and 
in  many  respects  the  most  typical  union  of  this  class,  is  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Makers.  This 
small  and  highly  skilled  class  of  handicraftsmen,  some  of 
whom  still  work  in  their  own  homes,  have  been  strongly 

similar  regulation.  Hitherto,  as  the  secretary  of  the  union  explained,  no  limits 
had  been  set  to  the  working  day,  and  "some  strong  young  men  will  work  from 
three  in  the  morning  till  nine  at  night."  The  result  was  that  the  men  "found 
there  was  advantage  taken  by  their  employers  ;  and  that  where  there  was  a  differ- 
ence that  was  resorted  to."  And  the  London  Compositors  expressly  stipulated 
in  the  Scale  of  Prices  accepted  by  the  employers  in  1810,  that  the  time  of  begin- 
ning work  should  be  formally  agreed  upon  between  the  master  and  the  "  com- 
panionship "  ;  that  it  should  be  uniform  for  all  the  men  ;  and  that  night  or 
Sunday  work  should  be  paid  for  at  higher  rates. 


The  Normal  Day  343 

combined  for  more  than  a  century,  and  have,  from  the  first, 
strictly  maintained  a  Standard  List  of  prices.  But  working 
invariably  by  hand,  paid  by  the  piece,  and  enjoying  a 
customary  privilege  of  coming  in  and  out  of  the  employer's 
workshop  as  they  thought  fit,  they  have  never  troubled  to 
settle  a  Normal  Day.  Although  the  trade  has  been,  for 
half  a  century,  steadily  declining  before  the  competition  of 
the  machine-made  product,  the  workmen  have  not  been 
driven  to  consider  the  effect  of  their  irregular  hours  upon 
their  Standard  Rate.  In  olden  times  they  enforced  a  strict 
limitation  of  apprentices,  and  during  the  present  generation 
the  number  of  boys  who  have  learnt  the  trade  has  been  so 
small 1  that  the  highly  skilled  bootmaker,  supplying  the 
perfect  workmanship  called  for  by  a  class  of  rich  customers, 
has  maintained  what  are  really  monopoly  earnings.  A  some- 
what analogous  case  is  that  of  the  United  Society  of  Brush- 
makers,  a  strong  organisation  of  skilled  handworkers,  whose 
printed  lists  of  prices  have  been  accepted  by  the  employers  from 
1805  downwards.  In  this  trade,  where  handwork  has  always 
prevailed,  the  operatives,  who  are  individual  producers,  have 
from  time  immemorial  gone  in  and  out  of  the  employer's  work- 
shop when  they  chose.  For  the  protection  of  their  Standard 
Rate  they  have  clung  to  their  old  limitation  of  apprentices, 
and  have  never  yet  sought  to  enforce  a  Normal  Day.  But 
it  is  the  Sheffield  trades  which  furnish  the  great  majority  of 
unions  indifferent  to  the  Normal  Day.  Here  we  have  a 
system  of  individual  production  which  dates,  as  regards  its 
main  features,  from  the  last  century.  The  employer  gives 
work  out,  to  be  done  by  the  operative,  either  on  his  own 
"  wheel "  at  home,  or  on  one  temporarily  rented  in  a  public 
"  tenement  factory."  The  unions,  unable  properly  to  control 
the  Individual  Bargains  made  by  their  members,  who  receive 
and  return  their  work  alone,  and  at  irregular  intervals, 

1  This  is  due,  we  think,  partly  to  the  current  impression  that  hand  shoemaking 
is  rapidly  dying  out,  partly  to  the  abnormal  demand  for  boys  at  relatively  good 
wnges  in  the  enormously  expanding  machine  bootmaking  industry,  and  partly  to 
the  relatively  high  degree  of  technical  proficiency  now  required  to  obtain  employ- 
ment at  the  handmade  trade. 


344  Tirade  Union  Function 

struggle  fitfully  to  maintain  a  Standard  Rate  by  the  most 
archaic  regulations  on  apprenticeship.  The  practical  failure 
of  these  regulations,  and  the  constant  degradation  of  the 
rates,  leads  the  more  thoughtful  workmen  to  denounce  the 
whole  system  of  individual  production,  and  to  urge  its  super- 
session by  the  factory  system,  where  collective  regulation, 
both  of  wages  and  hours,  would  become  possible.  But  the 
average  Sheffield  cutler,  accustomed  to  the  apparent  personal 
liberty  of  his  present  life,  is  as  yet  proof  against  the  economic 
arguments  of  his  leaders. 

The  demand  for  a  Common  Rule  determining  the  work- 
ing hours  for  all  the  members  of  a  trade  is  therefore,  even  in 
the  Trade  Union  world  of  to-day,  neither  so  universal  nor 
so  unhesitating  as  the  insistence  on  a  Standard  Rate  of  pay- 
ment. On  the  other  hand,  the  regulation  of  hours  is  less 
complicated  and  more  uniform  than  the  regulation  of  wages. 
The  most  rigid  enforcement  of  an  absolutely  uniform 
Standard  Rate  is  not  inconsistent,  in  well-organised  trades, 
with  a  very  large  elasticity,  specially  devised  to  meet  the 
highly  complex  conditions  and  varying  circumstances  of 
modern  industry.  Any  such  elasticity  with  regard  to  the 
hours  of  labor  is  fatal  to  the  maintenance  of  a  Normal  Day. 
We  see  this  illustrated  by  the  actual  working  of  Trade 
Union  agreements  with  regard  to  "  Overtime."  As  soon  as 
the  employer  was  precluded  from  requiring  the  attendance 
of  his  workmen  for  as  long  as  he  might  choose,  he  very 
naturally  made  it  a  stipulation,  in  conceding  a  customary 
fixed  working  day,  that  some  provision  should  be  made  for 
emergencies.  It  might  any  day  become  important  to  him, 
owing  to  a  sudden  rush  of  pressing  orders  or  similar  causes, 
that  some  or  all  of  his  operatives  should  give  more  than  the 
usual  hours  of  work.  The  Trade  Union  leaders  found  no 
argument  against  this  claim.  Moreover  they  saw  their  way, 
as  they  thought,  to  making  the  privilege  a  source  of  extra 
wages  to  their  members.  It  was  generally  agreed  that  the 
overtime  so  worked  should  be  paid  for  at  a  higher  rate- 
frequently  "  time  and  a  quarter,"  or  "  time  and  a  half."  This 


The  Normal  Day  345 

arrangement  appeared  a  reasonable  compromise,  advantageous 
to  both  parties.  The  employers  gained  the  elasticity  which 
they  declared  to  be  necessary  to  the  profitable  carrying  on 
of  their  business,  and  were  able,  moreover,  to  take  full 
advantage  of  a  busy  season.  The  workmen,  on  the  other 
hand,  were  recompensed  by  a  higher  rate  of  payment  for  the 
disturbance  of  their  customary  arrangement  of  life,  and  the 
extra  strain  of  continuing  work  in  a  tired  state.  The  con- 
cession involved  a  deviation  from  the  Normal  Day,  but  the 
exaction  of  extra  rates  would,  it  was  supposed,  restrict  over- 
time to  real  emergencies.  For  a  whole  generation  accord- 
ingly, both  employers  and  workmen  regarded  the  arrangement 
with  complacenc)'. 

Further  experience  of  these  extra  rates  for  overtime  work 
has  convinced  nearly  all  Trade  Unionists  that  they  afford 
the  smallest  degree  of  protection  to  the  Normal  Day,  whilst 
they  are  productive  of  evil  consequences  to  both  parties.  In 
spite  of  the  extra  rates,  employers  have,  in  many  trades, 
adopted  the  practice  of  systematically  working  their  men 
for  one  or  two  hours  a  day  overtime,  for  months  at  a  stretch, 
and,  in  some  cases,  even  all  the  year  round.  In  the  engin- 
eering and  shipbuilding  trades  in  particular,  the  desire  for 
prompt  delivery,  in  years  of  good  trade,  appears  to  be  so 
great,  and  the  competition  for  orders  is  at  all  times  so  keen, 
that  each  employer  thinks  it  to  his  advantage  to  promise  to 
complete  the  machine,  or  launch  the  vessel,  at  the  earliest 
possible  date.  The  result  is  that  the  long  hours  become 
customary,  and  subject  to  alteration  at  the  will  of  the  em- 
ployer. Nor  has  the  individual  workman  any  genuine 
choice.  An  establishment  in  which  it  is  a  constant  practice 
to  work  ten  or  twenty  hours  a  week  overtime,  does  not  long 
retain  in  employment  a  workman  who  prefers  his  leisure  to 
the  extra  payment,  and  who  therefore  leaves  his  bench  or 
his  forge  vacant  when  the  clock  strikes. 

Whilst  the  practice  of  systematic  overtime  deprives  the 
workman  of  any  control  over  his  hours  of  labor,  the  Trade 
Unionists  are  beginning  to  realise  that  it  insidiously  affects 


346  Trade  Union  Function 

also  the  rate  of  wages.  If  there  is  any  truth  in  the 
economists'  assumption  that  it  is  the  customary  standard 
of  life  of  each  class  of  workers  which,  in  the  long  run,  subtly 
determines  their  average  weekly  earnings,  systematic  overtime, 
if  paid  for  as  an  extra,  must,  it  is  clear,  tend  to  lower  the 
rate  per  hour.  That  frequent  opportunities  are  afforded  for 
working  overtime  is,  in  fact,  often  given  by  employers  as  an 
excuse  for  paying  a  low  rate  of  weekly  wages.  Where  pay- 
ment is  made  by  the  piece,  it  is  usually  impossible  in  practice 
to  distinguish  between  "  time  "  and  "  overtime,"  1  and  in  such 
cases  a  promise  of  systematic  overtime,  enabling  the  men  to 
make  up  their  total  earnings  to  the  old  standard,  is  a  common 
inducement  to  them  to  submit  to  a  reduction  of  their  piece- 
work rates.  But  the  timeworker  is,  in  reality,  as  much  at 
the  mercy  of  the  employer  as  the  pieceworker.  The  promise 
of  "  time  and  a  quarter "  for  the  extra  hours  is  a  powerful 
temptation  to  the  stronger  men  to  acquiesce  in  a  reduction 
of  the  Standard  Rate  of  payment  for  the  normal  working  day. 
Moreover,  when  bad  times  come,  and  the  demand  for  a 
particular  kind  of  labor  falls  off,  there  is  an  almost  irre- 
sistible tendency  for  the  amount  of  the  overtime  to  increase. 
The  employers  see  in  it  a  chance  of  reducing  the  cost  of 
production  by  spreading  the  heavy  items  of  rent,  interest  on 
machinery,  and  office  charges  over  more  hours  of  work. 

1  A  firm  desiring  to  work  overtime  has  thus  a  special  inducement  to  introduce 
payment  by  the  piece,  and  this  has  led,  in  some  districts  of  the  engineering  trade, 
to  the  total  destruction  of  Collective  Bargaining. — The  Report  specially  prepared 
by  t/ie  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  for  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor 
(London,  1892),  which  gives  the  result  of  an  inquiry  made  of  the  branches  as  to 
the  relative  prevalence  of  Overtime  and  Piecework  in  the  several  towns  of  the 
kingdom.  It  is  significant  that  it  is  the  machine-making  centres,  Keighley,  Col- 
chester, Gainsborough,  Ipswich,  Lincoln,  and  Derby  that  stand  out  as  having  the 
lowest  Standard  Rates  (275.  to  295.  per  week).  Every  one  of  these  branches 
reports  the  prevalence  of  systematic  overtime  to  a  large  extent,  and  of  piecework. 
The  case  would  be  even  stronger  if  statistics  could  be  obtained  from  unorganised 
districts  and  non-union  firms,  where  competitive  piecework  and  systematic  over- 
time are  the  invariable  accompaniments  of  low  rates.  "For  many  years  past," 
writes  Mr.  Tom  Mann,  "it  has  been  the  deliberate  practice  in  some  of  the 
agricultural  machine  shops  to  run  a  quarter  [day]  overtime  five  nights  in  the 
week,  and  in  consequence  of  this  the  Standard  Rate  is  very  low,  and  the  actual 
working  day  is  one  of  twelve  hours." — Amalgamated  Engineers'  Monthly  Journal, 
January  1897,  p.  12. 


The  Normal  Day  347 

The  workmen  are  tempted  to  make  up,  by  extra  labor,  their 
drooping  weekly  earnings.  Exactly  at  the  moment  when 
the  community  needs,  perhaps,  ten  per  cent  less  work  from 
its  engineers  or  its  building  operatives,  a  large  number  of 
these  are  pressed  and  tempted  to  give  ten  per  cent  more 
work — to  the  end  that  nearly  twenty  per  cent  of  the  trade 
can  find  no  employment  whatever !  The  barrister  or  the 
medical  man,  when  the  demand  for  his  labor  is  slack,  is  not 
expected  or  desired  to  work  more  hours  in  the  day.  The 
old-fashioned  handicraftsman  equally  reduced  his  working 
hours  in  slack  times,  and  increased  them  when  trade  was 
brisk.  In  the  case  of  the  great  machine  industries  the  tend- 
ency is,  in  the  absence  of  a  precisely  fixed  and  rigid  Normal 
Day,  all  in  the  contrary  direction.  It  is  impossible  to  con- 
vince the  Trade  Unionist  of  the  excellence  of  an  arrangement 
which  periodically  results  in  an  extra  large  percentage  of 
members  draining  the  society's  funds  by  Out-of-Work  Pay, 
at  the  very  moment  that  other  members  are  working  an 
extra  large  number  of  hours  overtime.  Even  the  employers 
are  now  beginning  to  object  to  the  arrangement.  They  feel 
that  it  is  unbusinesslike  to  pay  higher  rates  for  tired  work. 
And  they  assert  that  the  men's  desire  to  get  these  higher 
rates  sometimes  leads  to  dawdling  during  the  day,  in  order 
that  the  overtime  may  be  prolonged.1 

The  necessity  for  precision  and  uniformity  in  the  deter- 
mination of  the  working  hours  has  been  found  by  experience 
to  be  equally  absolute  where  the  Normal  Day  is  enforced  by 
the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment.  The  elaborate  code  which 
now  regulates  the  hours  of  labor  of  women  and  children  in 
British  industry  consists  of  two  main  divisions,  relating  re- 
spectively to  textile  manufacture  and  to  other  industries,  the 

1  The  really  unprofitable  character  of  systematic  overtime  was  detected  by  a 
shrewd  German  lawyer  in  1777.  Justus  Mb'ser  relates  that  when  the  building 
operatives  worked  overtime  on  his  new  house,  he  saw  himself  thereby  defrauded, 
as  the  men  in  the  long  hours  really  got  through  in  the  aggregate  less  work  in 
return  for  the  day's  pay.  "  Public  authority,"  he  adds,  "  should  here  intervene 
and  forbid  overtime,  which  is  a  fraud  on  the  employer  and  the  customer  alike." — 
"On  the  Work  clone  in  the  Hours  of  Recreation,"  in  Patriotische  Phantasien 
(Berlin,  1858),  vol.  iii.  p.  151,  noticed  \n'R'ce\i\.a.\\Q'sArbeitszeitundArbettsleistung. 


348  Trade  Union  Function 

former  dating  practically  from  1833,  the  latter,  it  may  almost 
be  said,  only  from  1867.  This  difference  in  antiquity  is 
reflected  in  the  varying  degree  of  rigidity  attained. 

Dealing  first  with  the  Normal  Day  in  textile  manu- 
factures, the  Act  of  1833  (which  applied,  in  express  terms, 
only  to  persons  under  eighteen  years  of  age)  prescribed  a 
maximum  of  twelve  hours  a  day,  less  one  and  a  half  hours  for 
meals.  But  it  left  it  open  to  the  discretion  of  the  millowners 
to  have  their  factories  open  any  hours  between  5.30  A.M. 
and  8.30  r.M.,  and  to  fix  the  meal-times  as  they  chose,  whilst 
time  lost  through  breakdown  of  machinery  might  be  made 
up  as  overtime.  The  factory  inspectors  soon  found  that  this 
elasticity  destroyed  the  efficacy  of  the  law.  We  need  not 
relate  the  incidents  of  the  long  struggle  waged  by  the 
Cotton  Operatives'  unions  to  secure  a  genuine  limitation  of 
the  factory  day.  One  by  one  the  loopholes  for  evasion  were 
closed  up.  The  right  to  make  up  time  lost  by  breakdowns 
was  (as  regards  mills  worked  by  steam)  expressly  abolished, 
the  hours  of  beginning  and  ending  work  were  definitely 
prescribed,  the  times  for  meals  were  fixed,  all  hours  were  to 
be  reckoned  by  a  public  clock.  In  short,  by  the  Acts  of 
1847,  1850,  and  1874  the  right  of  the  millowner  to  work 
any  extra,  or  even  any  different,  hours  from  those  prescribed 
by  law,  on  any  excuse  whatsoever,  has  been  absolutely  taken 
away.  However  much  the  circumstances  of  one  mill  or 
one  district  may  differ  from  those  of  another  ;  whatever  may 
be  the  nature  of  their  respective  trades  or  the  character  of 
their  markets  ;  whether  they  work  with  cotton  or  wool,  flax 
or  jute,  silk  or  worsted  ;  however  pressing  may  be  the  rush 
of  sudden  orders  ;  whatever  time  may  have  been  lost  by  an 
accident  to  the  boiler ;  the  precisely  determined  Normal 
Day  for  the  protected  classes  in  a  textile  mill  must  not  be 
encroached  upon,  and  may  not  even  be  temporarily  varied 
to  suit  the  convenience  either  of  employer  or  operatives. 
In  the  case  of  the  textile  industry  sixty  years'  experience 
enabled  the  Trade  Unionists  to  persuade  the  expert  officials 
of  the  Factory  Department,  and  even  a  reluctant  House  of 


The  Normal  Day  349 

Commons,  that  however  specious  may  be  the  arguments  for 
elasticity  and  qualifications,  it  is  only  by  the  rigid  enforce- 
ment of  precisely  fixed  and  uniform  hours  that  the  Normal 
Day  can  be  really  protected. 

In  other  trades,  in  which  factory  legislation  is  of  more 
recent  introduction,  we  see  the  same  lesson  in  process  of 
being  learnt.  Between  1860  and  1867  the  Ten  Hours' 
Normal  Day  was  introduced  for  the  protected  classes  in 
other  industries.  The  Act  of  1878  systematically  applied 
it  to  all  non- textile  factories  and  workshops.  But  the 
House  of  Commons  could  not  bring  itself  to  make  its 
uniform  rule  precise  and  effective.  Endeavors  were  made, 
by  sanctioning  overtime  under  certain  conditions,  by  en- 
abling the  hours  of  beginning  and  ending  work  to  be  varied, 
by  permitting  the  prescribed  meal-times  and  holidays  to 
be  altered,  and  by  exempting  particular  processes  from 
particular  restrictions,  to  meet  the  varying  circumstances  of 
different  industries.  So  deeply  rooted  was  the  feeling 
against  uniformity  that  the  exceptions  and  qualifications  of 
the  1878  Act  commended  themselves  even  to  the  Chief 
Inspector  of  Factories.  In  spite  of  his  experience  in  the 
textile  mills,  Mr.  Redgrave  could  welcome  with  complacency 
the  "  undulating  and  elastic  "  line  of  the  new  Act,  "  drawn  to 
satisfy  the  absolute  necessities  and  customs  of  different 
trades  in  different  parts  of  the  kingdom,"  especially  men- 
tioning the  "  extension  of  hours  to  meet  sudden  emergencies, 
as  the  case  of  occupations  in  which  the  operatives  have  to. 
meet  regular  slack  seasons." *  Twenty  years'  trial  of  this 
"  undulating  and  elastic  line "  has  convinced  the  officials 
administering  the  Act  that  no  such  uncertain  rule 
can  be  maintained.  The  whole  experience  of  the  Factory 
Department  proves  that  no  limitation  of  the  working 
day  can  really  be  enforced,  unless  there  are  uniform  and 
definitely  prescribed  hours  before  and  after  which  work 
must  not  be  carried  on.  The  overtime  regulations, 

1  Annual  Report  of  ff.M.  Chief  Inspector  of  Factories  and  Workshops,  1878 
(C.  2274  of  1879),  p.  5. 


Trade  Union  Function 

hailed  as  one  of  the  sensible  advantages  of  the  Act  of 
1878,  have  gone  far  to  neutralise  any  regulation  of  hours 
at  all.  The  report  of  the  Chief  Inspector  for  1894  is  full  of 
complaints  by  his  staff  of  the  impossibility  of  maintaining 
the  Normal  Day  in  face  of  the  "  partial,  unsound,  and  piece- 
meal privilege"  thus  given  to  unfair  employers,  and  of 
the  "  modifications "  which  constitute  "  a  most  weakening 
element  in  workshop  inspection." l  The  knowledge  that 
overtime  may  be  "  carried  on  for  forty-eight  times  in  a  year 
is  often  made,"  says  one  inspector,  "  an  excuse  for  working 
until  10  P.M.  for  three  or  four  nights  every  week  in  the 
season." 2  "  The  steady  increase  of  overtime  notices  which 
we  receive,"  declares  another,  "  leads  me  to  infer  that  .  .  . 
occupiers  of  factories  or  workshops  .  .  .  are  exercising  those 
privileges  without  due  regard  to  the  spirit  of  the  law,  which 
only  regards  overtime  as  an  exceptional  contingency,  only 
to  be  used  when  exceptional  circumstances  require  it.  ... 
Overtime  employment  leads  to  more  undetected  evasions  of 
the  laws  than  all  the  other  offences  under  factory  and 
workshop  legislation."  8 

Overtime,  in  fact,  is  to-day  seldom  the  "  exceptional  over- 
time "  contemplated  by  the  Act ;  but,  to  use  the  words  of 
one  inspector,  merely  a  means  of  enabling  the  employers  to 
"  keep  their  shops  open  late "  on  Saturday  nights,  and  of 
causing  "  females  to  be  kept "  systematically  late  at  work 
"  in  dressmaking  without  a  farthing  of  extra  remuneration." 4 
"  I  believe,  therefore,"  officially  reports  Miss  May  Abraham, 
Senior  Woman  Inspector  in  1893,  "  that  although  a  with- 
drawal of  the  overtime  exception  would  meet  with  protest 
from  employers  who  have  developed  its  use  from  an  excep- 
tion into  a  principle,  there  are'  some  who  would  welcome, 
and  many  who  would  be  indifferent  to  such  an  amendment ; 
that  the  large  class  of  employers  engaged  in  the  textile  and 

1  Report  of  the  Chief  Inspector  of  Factories  and  Workshops ',  1894  (C.  7745,  rf 
1895),  pp.  49,  50. 

2  Ibid.  p.  56  (Mr.  Mackie,  Assistant  Inspector). 

8  Ibid.  p.  194  (Mr.  Dodgson,  Inspector).  *  Ibid.  p.  191. 


The  Normal  Day  35 1 

allied  trades,  from  whom  permission  to  work  overtime  has 
been  rigidly  withheld,  would  greet  as  a  measure  of  justice  its 
withdrawal  now  from  trades  logically  no  more  entitled  to 
the  exception  than  their  own  :  and  that  by  the  workers  its 
abolition  would  be  welcomed  with  feelings  of  the  warmest 
gratitude." x  When  Mr.  Lakeman,  after  a  whole  genera- 
tion of  work  in  London  factory  inspection,  has  to  account  for 
the  long  and  irregular  hours  still  worked  in  defiance  of  the 
Act,  he  emphatically  declares  "  that  overtime  is  the  root  of 
the  mischief,  for  it  has  choked  the  law  with  partiality  and 
modifications."  2 

We  have  left  to  the  last  what  is  perhaps  the  most 
marked  distinction  between  the  Trade  Union  regulation  of 
the  Standard  Rate  and  that  of  the  Normal  Day.  Instead 
of  the  bewildering  variety  which  characterises  the  claim  to  a 
Standard  Rate,  where  each  trade,  and  each  section  of  a  trade, 
has  its  own  price,  we  have,  with  regard  to  the  Normal  Day, 
comparative  simplicity  and  uniformity.  During  the  last 
sixty  years,  the  demand  for  a  Normal  Day  has  come  in  the 
guise  of  a  succession  of  waves  of  popular  agitation  for  a 
common  and  uniform  reduction  of  the  hours  of  labor  for  all 
trades  alike.  The  Ten  Hours'  agitation  of  the  Lancashire 
Cotton  Operatives  spread,  as  we  have  seen,  to  the  builders, 
engineers,  tailors,  and  other  craftsmen,  and  resulted,  between 
1830  and  1840,  in  the  very  general  adoption  of  Ten  Hours 
as  the  Normal  Day  in  the  larger  towns.  Similarly,  the 
Nine  Hours'  Movement,  started  by  the  Stonemasons  in 
1846,  spread,  during  the  next  thirty  years,  throughout  the 
whole  range  of  industry,  and  resulted  by  1871-74  in  the 
almost  universal  acceptance  of  Nine  Hours  as  the  Normal 
Day  of  artisans,  mechanics,  and  factory  workers  and  the 
laborers  working  in  association  with  any  of  these  classes. 
And  it  may  perhaps  be  inferred  that  we  stand,  at  the 

1  Report  of  the  Chief  Inspector  of  Factories  and  Workshops  for  1893  (C.  7368 
of  1894),  pp.  ii,  12. 

2  Ibid.  p.  50.      See  also  the  Opinions  on  Overtime  (London,  1894),  published 
by  the  Women's  Trade  Union  League. 


35 2  Trade  Union  Fimction 

present  day,  in  the  first  years  of  a  similar  general  move- 
ment which  will  result  in  the  equally  widespread  adoption  of 
Eight  Hours  as  the  standard  working  day  in  all  branches  of 
British  industry.1 

Here  at  last  we  do  come  to  something  like  communistic 
feeling  among  British  workmen.  The  aristocratic  shipwright, 
pattern-maker,  or  cotton-spinner,  who  would  resent  the  idea 
that  the  unskilled  laborer  or  the  woman  worker  had  any 
moral  claim  to  as  high  a  Standard  Rate  as  himself,  readily 
accepts,  when  it  comes  to  a  question  of  hours,  the  doctrine 
of  complete  equality.  The  explanation  is  simple.  The  most 
rigid  class  distinctions  of  the  wage -earning  world  have,  in 
the  matter  of  hours  of  labor,  to  bend  before  the  mechanical 
necessity  for  a  Common  Rule.  The  same  economic  influ- 
ences which  make  it  impossible  for  each  weaver  in  a  mill  to 
come  in  and  out  as  he  or  she  chooses,  make  it  convenient, 

1  The  successive  reductions  in  working  hours  have  been  very  imperfectly 
recorded.  At  the  beginning  of  the  eighteenth  century,  the  ordinary  working  day 
of  indoor  trades  in  London  seems  to  have  been  from  6  A.M.  to  9  P.M.,  whilst  men 
working  out  of  doors  left  off  at  6  P.M.,  or  at  dark.  We  have  described  the  attempt 
of  the  tailors  in  1720  to  shorten  the  day  by  one  hour,  and  from  a  rare  work  in  the 
Guildhall  and  Patent  Office  Libraries,  dated  1747  (A  General  Description  of  All 
Trades,  Anon.),  it  would  seem  that,  by  the  middle  of  the  century,  a  few  other  trades 
had  followed  their  example.  The  bookbinders  (1787)  and  saddlers  (1793) 
secured  a  further  reduction  to  thirteen  hours  less  meal-times,  and  in  1794  the 
bookbinders  gained  what  would  now  be  called  a  io£  hours'  day  (12  hours  less 
meal-times).  Our  impression  is  that  at  the  opening  of  the  present  century  this 
had  become  in  London  the  usual  working  day  for  all  the  skilled  handicraft  trades 
working  by  time.  By  1834,  at  any  rate,  the  London  building  trades  had  secured 
a  ten  hours'  day  and  in  1836,  the  London  engineers  obtained  the  same  reduction. 
Within  ten  years  this  became  general  in  most  of  the  large  towns,  and  was  adopted 
for  the  textile  factories  in  the  celebrated  Ten  Hours'  Bill  of  1847.  Tne  Nine 
Hours'  Movement  begins  with  the  Liverpool  stonemasons  in  1846,  but  does  not 
become  general  until  1859-61,  nor  fully  successful  until  1871.  Meanwhile  an 
agitation  had  arisen  among  the  skilled  artisans  for  a  Saturday  half-holiday.  The 
building  trades  had  secured  a  "  four  o'clock  Saturday"  in  some  towns  by  1847, 
making  a  58^  hours'  week.  By  1861  this  had  become  in  London  a  "two 
o'clock  Saturday,"  or  56^  hours  a  week,  an  arrangement  which  was  adopted  for 
the  textile  factories  by  the  Act  of  1874.  When,  in  1871,  the  Nine  Hours'  Day 
was  won  by  the  engineering  and  building  trades,  it  took  the  form  of  1 1  hours  less 
i^  hours  meal- times,  for  five  days,  and  six  hours  less  half  an  hour  for  breakfast  on 
Saturday,  thus  securing  54  hours  with  a  "one  o'clock  Saturday."  In  1890  the 
engineering  trades  on  the  Tyne  and  Wear,  desiring  a  more  complete  half-holiday, 
demanded  and  obtained  a  "twelve  o'clock  Saturday"  (53  hours).  On  the  great 
general  revision  of  hours  in  the  London  building  trades  in  1892,  the  week  was 


The  Normal  Day  353 

if  not  absolutely  necessary,  for  the  hours  of  beginning  and 
leaving  off  work  to  be  identical,  not  for  the  weavers  only, 
but  also  for  all  the  different  classes  of  workpeople  employed 
in  the  establishment.  And  it  has  been  a  special  feature  of 
the  industrial  development  of  the  past  thirty  years  more  and 
more  to  include,  in  a  single  establishment,  not  merely  different 
sections  of  one  trade,  but  also  the  most  diverse  industrial 
processes  subsidiary  to  the  production  of  the  finished  article. 
In  the  leading  engineering  and  shipbuilding  yards  of  the 
Tyne  and  Clyde,  or  the  great  works  of  the  railway  com- 
panies— to  cite  only  a  few  out  of  many  examples — we  find 
to-day  workmen  of  a  hundred  different  trades  working  in  a 
single  establishment  whose  hours  of  labor  are  almost  neces- 
sarily governed  by  the  same  "  steam  hooter,"  or  factory  bell.1 
Any  regulations  relating  to  the  length  or  distribution  of 
the  working  day  tend,  therefore,  to  be  identical  for  all  classes 
of  operatives. 

fixed  at  50,  47,  and  44  hours  according  to  the  season,  averaging  484  hours 
through  the  year,  and  always  securing  the  Saturday  half-holiday.  Finally,  we 
have  the  adoption,  between  1889  and  1897,  of  the  Eight  Hours'  Day  in  over  five 
hundred  establishments,  including  the  Government  dockyards  and  workshops, 
nearly  all  municipal  gasworks,  and  a  majority  of  the  London  engineering  and 
bookbinding  establishments,  together  with  isolated  firms  all  over  the  country. 

This  progressive  reduction  relates,  it  need  hardly  be  said,  only  to  the  nominal 
standard  hours  of  the  most  advanced  districts,  and  takes  no  account  either  of  the 
prevalence  of  overtime,  or  of  the  lingering  of  longer  hours  in  other  districts.  In 
the  absence  of  precise  and  authoritative  statistics  as  to  the  amount  of  overtime 
worked  at  different  periods  per  person  employed,  it  is  impossible  to  give  any 
inductive  proof  of  the  lengthening  of  hours  by  systematic  overtime  at  the  moment 
when,  owing  to  a  slackening  of  demand,  less  of  the  work  is  demanded  by  the 
community.  But  the  same  tendency  may  be  seen  in  the  recorded  changes  in  the 
Normal  Day  itself.  In  the  extraordinarily  busy  years  of  1871-72  the  engineering 
employers  had  agreed  with  the  Trade  Unions  that  the  week's  work  should 
be  54  hours,  and,  on  the  Clyde,  51  hours  only.  When  the  great  stagnation 
of  1878-79  fell  upon  the  industry,  and  there  was  much  less  engineering  work 
to  be  done,  the  employers  decided  "  that  the  time  has  arrived  .  .  .  when  the 
idle  hours  which  have  been  unprofitably  thrown  away,  must  be  reclaimed  to 
industry  and  profit,  by  being  redirected  to  reproductive  work  "  (Secret  Circular  of 
the  Iron  Trades  Employers'  Association,  December  1878).  They  therefore  made 
a  general  attempt  to  increase  the  week's  work  to  57  or  59  hours.  A  similar 
attempt  was  made  in  the  building  trades.  For  an  account  of  this  backwardation 
in  hours,  see  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  331,  334. 

1  See,  for  this  tendency  to  an  "  integration  of  processes  "  in  competitive  industry, 
the  Economic  Heresies  of  the  London  County  Council^  by  Sidney  Webb  (London, 
1894),  a  paper  read  at  the  Economic  Section  of  the  British  Association  in  1894. 
VOL.  I  2  A 


CHAPTER    VII 

SANITATION    AND    SAFETY 

IN  the  great  establishments  of  modern  industry,  where  large 
numbers  of  manual  workers  are  massed  together,  the  wage- 
contract  implicitly  includes  many  other  conditions  besides 
those  of  the  time  to  be  spent  in  labor,  and  the  rate  at  which 
this  is  to  be  paid  for.  The  wage-earner  sells  to  his  employer, 
not  merely  so  much  muscular  energy  or  mechanical  ingenuity, 
but  practically  his  whole  existence  during  the  working  day.1 
An  overcrowded  or  badly-ventilated  workshop  may  exhaust 
his  energies  ;  sewer  gas  or  poisonous  material  may  under- 
mine his  health ;  badly -constructed  plant  or  imperfect 
machinery  may  maim  him  or  even  cut  short  his  days  ; 
coarsening  surroundings  may  brutalise  his  life  and  degrade 
his  character — yet,  when  he  accepts  employment,  he  tacitly 
undertakes  to  mind  whatever  machinery,  use  whatever 
materials,  breathe  whatever  atmosphere,  and  endure  what- 
ever sights,  sounds,  and  smells  he  may  find  in  the  employer's 
workshop,  however  inimical  they  may  be  to  health  or  safety. 
On  all  these  points  Individual  Bargaining  is  out  of  the 
question.  The  most  ingenious  employer  would  find  it 
impossible  to  bargain  separately  with  individual  workers  as 

1  "It  matters  nothing  to  the  seller  of  bricks  whether  they  are  to  be  used  in 
building  a  palace  or  a  sewer  ;  but  it  matters  a  great  deal  to  the  seller  of  labor, 
who  undertakes  to  perform  a  task  of  given  difficulty,  whether  or  not  the  place  in 
which  it  is  to  be  done  is  a  wholesome  and  a  pleasant  one,  and  whether  or 
not  his  associates  will  be  such  as  he  cares  to  have." — Principles  of  Economics^ 
by  Professor  A.  Marshall  (London,  1895),  3rd  edit-  P-  646- 


Sanitation  and  Safety  355 

to  the  temperature  of  the  workshop  or  the  use  of  the 
ventilating  fan,  the  fencing  of  the  machinery  or  the  provision 
of  sanitary  accommodation  :  he  cannot  make  any  particular 
concession  to  a  consumptive  weaver  in  the  matter  of  the 
amount  of  steam  to  be  injected  into  the  weaving  shed,  or 
give  special  terms  to  a  cautious  miner  with  regard  to  the 
construction  of  the  cage  or  the  thickness  of  the  rope  on 
which  his  life  will  depend.  These  conditions  are  necessarily 
identical  for  all  the  operatives  concerned.  The  issue,  therefore, 
is  not  whether  there  shall  be  a  Common  Rule  excluding  the 
exigencies  of  particular  workers,  but  by  whom  and  in  whose 
interest  that  Common  Rule  shall  be  made.1 

The  Trade  Unionist  demands  for  safe,  healthy,  and  com- 
fortable conditions  of  work  appear  to  date  only  from  about 
1 840,  and  can  scarcely  be  said  to  have  become  a  definite  part  of 
Trade  Union  policy  until  about  iS/i.2  This  long-continued 
indifference  to  the  risks  of  accident  and  disease  was,  as  we 
need  hardly  remind  the  reader,  common  to  all  classes.  So 
long  as  sickness  and  casualties  were  regarded  as  "  visitations 

1  The  individual  operative   "  can  quarrel  no  more  with  the  foul  air  of  his 
unventilated  factory,  burdened  with  poisons,  than  he  can  quarrel  with  the  great 
wheel  that  turns  below  "  (The  Wages  Question,  by  Francis  A.  Walker,  New  York, 
1876,  London,  1891,  p.   359).      "Where  a  large  number  of  men  are  employed 
together  in  a  factory  ...   all  must  conform  to  the  wishes  of  the  majority,  or  the 
will  of  the  employers,  or  the  customs  of  the  trade." — The  State  in  Relation  to 
Labour,  by  W.  Stanley  Jevons  (London,  1887),  p.  65. 

2  The  coalminers,  however,  always  asked  for  safeguards  against  the  perils  of 
the  mine.     As  early  as  1662,  it  is  said  that  2000  colliers  of  Northumberland  and 
Durham  prepared  a  petition  to  the  King,  asking,  among  other  things,  that  the 
mine  owners  should  be  required  to  provide  better  ventilation  of  the  pits.     Already 
in  1676,  the  Government,  in  the  person  of  the  Lord  Keeper  North,  was  suggesting 
that  a  second  shaft  ought  always  to  be  provided  (The  Miners  of  Northumberland 
and  Durham,  by  Richard  Fynes,  Blyth,  1873).      Similar  desires  were  expressed 
by  the  earliest  of  the  Miners'  unions  in  1809  and  1825,  and  in  such  pamphlets 
as  A    Voice  from  the  Coalmines,  or  a  Plain  Statement  of  the  grievances  of  the 
pitmen  of  the  Tyne  and  Wear  (South  Shields,   1825),  and  An  earnest  address 
and  urgent  appeal  to  the  people    of  England  on  behalf  of  the   oppressed  and 
suffering  pitmen  of  the  Counties  of  Northumberland  and  Durham   (Newcastle, 
1831).     In  no  other  industry  do  we  trace  any  request  prior  to   1840  for  more 
sanitary  conditions  of  employment  (as  distinguished  from  higher  wages  or  shorter 
hours).      Neither  in  the  Parliamentary  inquiries  of  1824,  1825,  and  1838,  nor  in 
the  numerous  investigations  of  the  Commissioners  connected  with  the  Factory 
Acts,   Poor  Law,  or  Health  of  Towns,  have  we  found  any  evidence  that  the 
operatives  of  that  time  pressed  for  healthier  conditions  of  work. 


356  Trade  Union  Function 


of  God,"  to  be  warded  off  by  prayer  and  fasting,  effective 
sanitary  regulations  were  not  to  be  expected  either  from 
the  workmen's  combinations  or  from  Parliament  itself.1 
And  whilst  the  theologian  was  attributing  the  workman's 
ill -health  to  the  Act  of  God,  the  political  economist 
was  assuring  him  that  any  unusual  risk  to  health  or  life, 
like  any  extra  discomfort,  inevitably  brought  with  it  sub- 
stantial compensation  in  the  shape  of  higher  wages.  We 
therefore  find  that  in  the  comparatively  few  cases  between 
1700  and  1840,  in  which  Trade  Unions  made  any  complaint 
of  dangerous  or  insanitary  conditions,  they  brought  forward 
the  grievance  without  any  idea  of  establishing  regulations  to 
prevent  such  conditions  for  the  future,  but  merely  as  an 
argument  in  favor  of  the  concession  of  shorter  hours  or  higher 
wages.2  We  need  not  follow  the  gradual  disappearance  of 
the  theological  explanation  of  disease  before  the  progress  of 
science.  Of  greater  interest  to  the  economic  student  is  the 
growth  of  an  opinion  among  the  Trade  Unionists,  that  the 
compensation  for  insanitary  conditions  brought  about  by 
"  the  free  play  of  natural  forces,"  was  of  a  totally  different 
character  from  that  prophesied  by  Adam  Smith  and  his 
followers.  To  the  intelligent  Trade  Union  official  it  became 
increasingly  evident  that  the  compensatory  effect  of  bad 
conditions  of  employment  took  the  form,  not  of  higher  rates 

1  Public  health  legislation  dates  only  from  about  1840 ;  see  Glen,  Histoy  of 
the  Law  relating  to  Public  Health,  loth  edition  (London,  1888).     The  first  general 
Public  Health  Act  was  not  passed  until  1848. 

2  Thus,  when  in  1752,  the  combination  of  journeymen  tailors  of  London  com- 
plained that,  by  their  having  to  work  from  six  in  the  morning  until  eight  at  night, 
"  sitting  so  many  hours  in  such  a  position,  almost  double  on  the  shopboard,  with 
their  legs  under  them,  and  poring  so  long  over  their  work  by  candlelight,  their 
spirits  are  exhausted,  nature  is  wearied  out,  and  their  health  and  sight  are  soon 
impaired,"  all  they  asked  for  was  an  extra  sixpence  a  day  wages  (77ie  Tailoring 
Trade,  by  F.  W.  Gallon,  London,  1896,  p.  53  ;  published  by  the  London  School 
of  Economics  and  Political  Science).     And  when,  in   1777,  the  far-sighted  and 
observant  Justus  Moser  was  impressed  by  the  injury  to  health  caused  by  the 
conditions  under  which  apprentices  and  young  journeymen  were  put   to  work, 
nothing  in  the  nature  of  factory  legislation  occurred  to  him  ;  his  remedy  was  a 
technical  institute  which  should  supersede  apprenticeship  altogether. — "  Is  not 
an  Institute  required  for  Artisans  ?"  in  Patriotische  Phantasien  (Berlin,  1858), 
vol.  Hi.  p.  135. 


Sanitation  and  Safety  357 

paid  by  the  employer,  but  of  a  lower  grade  of  character 
among  the  workpeople.  When  the  conditions  of  safety, 
health,  and  comfort  in  the  trade  fell  below  the  standard  of 
other  occupations,  the  Trade  Union  official  did  not  find  that 
his  members  got  higher  wages.1  What  happened  was  that 
his  union  was  presently  made  up  of  workers  of  coarser  fibre, 
worse  character,  and  more  irregular  habits.  And  this  result 
was  brought  about  not  entirely,  or  even  mainly,  by  the 
refusal  of  respectable  persons  to  enter  trades  in  which  the 
risks  to  life,  health,  and  character  were  exceptionally  great. 
For  the  great  mass  of  workers,  in  districts  dependent  on 
particular  industries,  there  was  practically  no  choice  of  occu- 
pation, and  hence,  over  large  areas  of  the  United  Kingdom, 
physical  enfeeblement  and  moral  deterioration  became  the 
lot  of  good  and  bad  alike.  Even  in  the  rare  cases  in  which 
exceptionally  strong  unions  obtained  for  their  members  some 
definite  compensation  for  risk  of  disease  and  death,  the  more 
thoughtful  workmen  could  not  fail  to  realise  that  the  extra 
money  was  no  real  equivalent  for  the  lives  prematurely  cut 
short,  the  constitutions  ruined  by  disease,  or  the  characters 
brutalised  by  coarsening  surroundings. 

Thus,  in  the  Trade  Union  world  of  to-day,  there  is  no 
subject  on  which  workmen  of  all  shades  of  opinion,  and  all 
varieties  of  occupation,  are  so  unanimous,  and  so  ready  to 
take  combined  action,  as  the  prevention  of  accidents  and  the 
provision  of  healthy  workplaces.  We  do  not  propose  to 
enumerate,  or  even  to  summarise  in  any  detail,  the  various 
regulations  upon  which  Trade  Unions  have  insisted  for  the 
protection  of  the  life,  health,  and  comfort  of  their  members. 
These  necessarily  differ  from  trade  to  trade  according  to  the 

1  For  over  a  century  economic  manuals  have  reproduced  Adam  Smith's 
celebrated  analysis  of  the  causes  of  differences  in  wages,  without  any  investigation 
of  the  facts  of  industrial  life.  "  There  is  hardly  a  grain  of  truth,"  wrote  Fleeming 
Jenkin  with  refreshing  originality  in  1870,  "in  the  doctrine  that  men's  wages  are 
in  proportion  to  the  [un-]pleasantness  of  their  occupation.  On  the  contrary,  all 
loathsome  occupations  are  undertaken  by  apathetic  beings  for  a  miserable  hire.  .  . 
The  best  paid  is  [also]  the  most  pleasant  life." — "Graphic  Representation  of 
the  Laws  of  Supply  and  Demand,"  by  Fleeming  Jenkin,  in  Recess  Studies 
(London,  1870),  p.  182. 


358  Trade  Union  Function 

technical  processes  and  particular  grievances  of  the  industry, 
Sometimes  it  is  the  prevention  of  accidents  that  is  aimed  at. 
Thus,  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers  has  insisted,  in 
its  elaborate  agreement  with  the  Ship  Repairers'  Federation 
of  the  United  Kingdom,  upon  the  following  clause :  "  The 
employers  undertake  that,  before  men  are  put  to  work  on 
[repairing  the  great  tank  ships  for  carrying  petroleum  in 
bulk,  in  which  dangerous  vapour  accumulates],  an  expert's 
certificate  shall  be  obtained  daily  to  the  effect  that  the  tanks 
are  absolutely  safe.  Such  certificate  to  be  posted  in  sorm 
conspicuous  place."  *  Innumerable  other  regulations  aim  at 
the  removal  of  conditions  injurious  to  the  workers'  health. 
Thus,  the  various  Trade  Unions  of  "  ovenmen "  (potters] 
have  for  a  whole  generation  protested  against  being  fore 
to  empty  the  ovens  before  these  have  been  allowed  to 
cool,  on  the  express  ground  that  this  unnecessary  exposui 
to  a  temperature  between  170  and  210  degrees  Fahrenheit 
is  seriously  detrimental  to  health.  Several  strikes  hai 
taken  place  solely  on  this  point,  and  the  Staffordshire  Oven- 
men's  Union  now  has  a  by-law  authorising  the  support 
any  member  who  is  dismissed  for  refusing  to  work  in 
temperature  higher  than  120  degrees.2  The  Northern 
Counties  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton- 
weavers  has  repeatedly  withdrawn  its  members  from  weav- 
ing sheds  into  which  the  employers  insisted  on  injecting  an 
undue  volume  of  steam,  and  it  succeeded,  in  1889,  in  obtain- 
ing a  special  Act  defining  the  maximum  limit  to  which  thi< 
practice  might  be  carried.3  The  carelessness  of  employei 

1  Payment  for  repairs  on  oil  vessels :  Agreement  between  the  Ship  Repairers 
Federation  of  the  United  Kingdom  and  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  signed 
at  Newcastle,  I2th  January  1894.      Similar  agreements  have  been  made  by  tl 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  (Tyneside  District)  with  the  Federation  (I4th 
September  1894),  and  (Newport  and  Cardiff  District)  with  the  Engineers  and 
Shipbuilders  Employers'  Association  of  Newport  and  Cardiff,  2ist  March  1895, 
and  in  other  seaports. 

2  Information  given  to  us  by  the  officials  ;  see  also  Dr.  J.  T.  Arlidge,  The 
Pottery  Manufacture  in  its  Sanitary  Aspects  (London,  1892),  p.  17. 

3  Royal    Commission    on    Labor,    evidence    Group    C ;    the    Cotton    Cloth 
Factories  Act,  1889  (52  &  53  Viet.  c.  62),  amended  by  the  Factory  Acts  of  1891 
and  1895.      See  the  interesting  investigation  into  the  results  of  this  legislation  by 


Sanitation  and  Safety  359 

with  regard  to  the  sanitary  condition  of  the  places  in  which 
their  wage -earners  have  to  work  has  led  to  many  fitful 
struggles.  Perhaps  the  most  notable,  and  at  the  same  time 
significant  example  is  that  of  the  Glasgow  tailors.  As  far 
back  as  1854  we  find  the  union  resolving  that  the  members 
employed  in  a  certain  notorious  underground  cellar  "  should 
finish  their  jobs  and  leave,  until  a  better  workshop  was 
got."  ]  In  the  next  year  an  attempt  was  made  to  prohibit 
all  working  in  underground  rooms.  The  general  meeting 
resolved :  "  That  those  employers  who  have  pit-shops  at 
present  receive  notice  to  get  proper  workshops,  otherwise  the 
men  will  be  obliged  to  refuse  to  work  in  all  shops  the  same 
not  being  above  ground."  2  During  the  following  years,  the 
energetic  journeymen  tailors  put  into  force  all  the  methods 
of  Trade  Unionism  to  attain  their  end.  Mutual  Insurance 
was  employed  to  a  remarkable  extent,  any  member  choosing 
to  leave  an  underground  workshop  being  allowed  four  shillings 
a  week  over  and  above  the  ordinary  Out-of-Work  pay.  This 
induced  the  better  class  of  employers  to  resume  Collective 
Bargaining,  to  agree  to  provide  suitable  workrooms  for  their 
men,  and  even  to  submit  them  to  the  inspection  of  the 
Trade  Union  officials.  But  neither  Mutual  Insurance  nor 
Collective  Bargaining  availed  to  put  down  the  evil  among  the 
worst  employers.  The  union  then  turned  to  the  law.  An  in- 
fluentially  signed  memorial  was  presented  to  the  Town  Council 
in  order  to  obtain  a  by-law  prohibiting  the  use  of  underground 
workshops  altogether,  and  though  this  request  does  not  appear 
to  have  been  complied  with,  the  increasing  stringency  of  the 
sanitary  law  to  some  extent  served  the  purpose.3 

a  Home  Office  Committee  of  experts,  Report  of  a  Committee  appointed  to  inquire 
into  the  -working  of  the  Cotton  Cloth  Factories  Act,  1889  [C,  8348],  1897. 

1  MS.  Minutes  of  Glasgow  Tailors'  Society,  April  1854. 

2  Ibid.  January  1855. 

3  Report  on  Trade  Societies  and  Strikes :  National  Association  for  the  Promo- 
tion of  Social  Science,  1860,  p.  280,  where  it  is  erroneously  stated  that  the  clause 
desired  was  actually  embodied  in  a  local  Act  of  Parliament.     We  can  trace  no 
such  provision,  and  underground  workshops  are,  if  properly  ventilated,  still  per- 
mitted by  law.      But  the  use  of  premises  below  the  ground-level  as  dwellings  is 
restricted  by  the  Public  Health  Acts,  and  the  Factory  Act  of  1895,  sec.  27, 


360  Trade  Union  Function 

But  safety  and  health  are  not  the  only  requirements. 
Many  trades  enforce  a  series  of  regulations  designed  merely 
to  secure  the  comfort  and  convenience  of  the  operatives.  In 
the  innumerable  "  Working  Rules  "  which  govern  the  build- 
ing trades  of  the  various  towns,  the  Trade  Unions  generally 
insist  on  a  clause  to  compel  the  employer  to  provide  a  dry 
and  comfortable  place  in  which  the  men  may  take  their 
meals,  lock  up  their  tools  in  safety,  and  rest  under  cover  in 
storms  of  rain.1 

It  will  be  unnecessary  to  give  further  examples.  The  long 
and  elaborate  code  of  law  which  now  governs  employment 
in  the  factory  and  workshop,  the  bakehouse  and  printing 
office,  on  sea  and  in  the  depths  of  the  mine,  is  itself  largely 
made  up  of  the  Common  Rules  designed  for  the  protection 
of  the  operatives'  health,  life,  or  comfort,  which  have  been 
pressed  for  by  Trade  Unions,  and  have  successively  com- 
mended themselves  to  the  wisdom  of  Parliament.  And  the 
Trade  Union  Regulations  of  this  class,  whether  enforced  by 
the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining  or  by  that  of  Legal 
Enactment,  are  constantly  increasing  in  number  and  variety. 
Every  revision  of  "  Working  Rules,"  or  other  collective 
agreements  with  employers,  is  made  the  occasion  for  new 
stipulations.  Each  meeting  of  the  Trade  Union  Congress 
sees  new  proposals  under  this  head  formally  endorsed  by  the 
representatives  of  other  trades.  Scarcely  a  session  of  Parlia- 
ment now  passes  without  new  Common  Rules  for  the  pro- 
forbids  the  occupation  of  any  such  premises  as  bakehouses  if  they  were  not 
actually  employed  as  soch  on  1st  January  1896. 

1  Thus,  to  give  only  four  instances  out  of  our  collection  of  many  hundreds, 
the  London  Stone  Carvers  are  found  insisting,  as  early  as  1876,  "that,  as  a  pro- 
tection from  the  weather,  and  to  prevent  loss  of  time,  all  carvers  on  outdoor  jobs 
to  be  supplied  with  tarpaulins  or  other  suitable  covering  "  ;  the  London  Plasterers 
stipulate  (1892)  that  "employers  shall  provide,  where  practicable  and  reasonable, 
a  suitable  place  for  the  workmen  to  have  their  meals  on  the  works,  with  a 
laborer  to  assist  in  preparing  them  "  ;  the  Nottingham  Bricklayers  require  (1893) 
"  that  there  shall  be  a  lock-up  shop  provided  for  workmen  to  get  their  meals  in 
and  put  their  tools  in  safety";  and  the  Portsmouth  Stonemasons  (1893)  insist 
"  that  suitable  shops  and  mess-houses  be  erected  on  all  jobs  where  necessary." 
All  these  Working  Rules,  it  will  be  remembered,  are  formally  agreed  to  and 
signed  by  the  representatives  of  the  employers  and  the  Trade  Union. 


Sanitation  and  Safety  361 

tection  of  the  health  or  safety  of  one  or  other  class  of 
operatives  being,  amid  general  public  approval,  added  to  our 
Labor  Code.1 

We  attribute  the  rapid  development  of  this  side  of  Trade 
Unionism  to  the  discovery  by  the  Trade  Union  leaders  that 
it  is  the  line  of  least  resistance.  Middle-class  public  opinion, 
which  fails  as  yet  to  comprehend  the  Common  Rule  of  the 
Standard  Rate  and  is  strongly  prejudiced  against  the  fixing 
of  a  Normal  Day,  cordially  approves  any  proposal  for  pre- 
venting accidents  or  improving  the  sanitation  of  workplaces. 
The  alacrity  with  which  capitalist  Parliaments  met  these 
requests  came  as  a  surprise  to  the  Trade  Union  officials. 
To  the  sweated  journeyman  tailor  at  the  East  End,  the  fact 
that  he  was  compelled  to  labor  in  an  overcrowded  workroom 
seemed  less  detrimental  to  his  health  than  the  excessive 
hours  of  daily  toil  that  were  exacted  from  him.  The  girls 
in  a  London  jam  factory  are  still  puzzled  as  to  why  the 
Government  should  compel  their  employer  to  provide  them 
with  costly  sanitary  conveniences,  and  yet  permit  him  to  go 
on  paying  wages  quite  inadequate  for  their  healthy  subsist- 
ence. It  cannot  be  of  more  urgent  importance  to  the  com- 
munity to  insist  on  sanitary  refinements  than  to  secure  the 
fundamental  requisites  of  healthy  life  and  citizenship.  Nor 
is  one  set  of  Common  Rules  less  inconsistent  with  "  freedom 
of  enterprise"  than  the  other.  With  regard  to  Sanitation 
and  Safety  the  law  has  not  scrupled  to  "  thrust  a  ramrod  " 
into  the  delicate  mechanism  of  British  industry,  in  the  shape 
of  rigid  rules  enforced  on  all  manufacturers  alike.  Whether 
a  factory  be  new  or  old,  large  or  small,  in  the  crowded  slums 
of  a  manufacturing  town  or  on  the  breezy  uplands  of  the 
country  side,  gaining  huge  profits  for  its  proprietor  or  actually 
running  at  a  loss,  the  community  insists  on  the  observance 
of  uniform  rules  as  to  cubic  space,  ventilation,  meal-times, 
stoppages  for  cleaning,  fire-escapes,  doors  opening  outwards, 

1  During  the  ten  years,  1887-1896,  there  were  passed  no  fewer  than  thirteen 
separate  Acts  relating  to  the  conditions  of  employment  in  factories,  workshops, 
mines,  shops,  or  railways,  besides  several  general  Public  Health  Acts. 


362  Trade  Union  Function 

fencing  of  machinery,  degrees  of  humidity  and  temperature, 
water  supply,  drainage,  and  sanitary  conveniences,  separate 
for  each  sex.  It  is  in  vain  that  the  manufacturers  point  out 
to  the  House  of  Commons  that  these  requirements  constitute 
as  real  and  as  burdensome  an  increase  in  their  cost  of  pro- 
duction as  a  shortening  of  the  hours  of  labor,  and  that  the 
Factory  Inspector's  requisition  for  a  ventilating  fan  and  the 
erection  of  additional  sanitary  conveniences  may  result  in  the 
actual  closing  of  the  oldest  and  least  profitable  mills. 

It  is  not  easy  to  find  an  adequate  explanation  of  this 
state  of  mind.  Something,  we  think,  is  to  be  attributed  to 
the  general  fear  of  infectious  disease,  which  the  ordinary 
middle -class  man  associates  more  with  overcrowding  and 
defective  sanitation  than  with  insufficient  food  or  overtaxed 
energies.  Along  with  this  fear  of  infection  there  goes  a  real 
sympathy  for  the  sufferers,  ill-health  and  accidents  being 
calamities  common  to  rich  and  poor.  More,  perhaps,  is  due 
to  the  half-conscious  admission  that,  as  regards  Sanitation 
and  Safety  at  any  rate,  the  Trade  Union  argument  is  borne 
out  by  facts,  and  that  it  is  impracticable  for  the  individual 
operative  to  bargain  about  these  conditions  of  his  labor. 
And  another  factor  may  come  into  the  decision.  There  still 
exists  a  certain  scepticism  as  to  whether  the  wage-earner  is 
capable  of  wisely  expending  any  larger  wages  than  will  keep 
body  and  soul  together,  or  of  usefully  employing  any  greater 
leisure  than  is  necessary  for  sleep.1  Ventilating  bricks  and 
shuttle-guards,  whitewash  and  water-closets  cannot  be  spent 
in  drink  or  wasted  in  betting.  Mingled  with  this  economic 
consideration  there  is  even  a  subtle  element  of  Puritanism — 
the  vicarious  asceticism  of  a  luxurious  class — which  prefers 

1  To  the  Iron  Trades  Employers'  Association  of  1878 — an  organisation  which 
included  the  leading  captains  of  British  industry — a  reduction  of  wages  and  a 
lengthening  of  hours  appeared  a  positive  economic  advantage  to  the  community. 
"It  has  appeared  to  employers  of  labor,"  said  their  secret  circular  urging  a 
return  to  longer  hours  of  labor  and  a  general  reduction  of  rates  of  payment, 
"  that  the  time  has  arrived  when  the  superfluous  wages  which  have  been  dissipated 
in  unproductive  consumption  must  be  retrenched,  and  when  the  idle  hours  which 
have  been  unprofitably  thrown  away  must  be  reclaimed  to  industry  and  profit  by 
being  redirected  to  reproductive  work." — History  of  Trade  Unionism,  p.  331. 


Sanitation  and  Safety  363 

to  give  the  poor  "  what  is  good  for  them,"  rather  than  that 
in  which  they  can  find  active  enjoyment. 

With  public  opinion  in  this  state,  and  a  House  of  Com- 
mons predisposed  to  favor  sanitary  legislation,  it  might  be 
imagined  that  the  necessary  Common  Rules  for  securing 
health  and  safety  would  have  been  systematically  applied  to 
every  industry.  This,  however,  is  not  the  British  way  of 
doing  things.  Neither  the  permanent  officials  of  the  Home 
Office,  nor  even  the  Cabinet  Ministers  themselves,  ever  dream 
of  considering  it  their  duty  to  discover  and  investigate  evils 
which  have  not  been  formally  brought  to  their  notice,  nor 
spontaneously  to  initiate  remedial  measures  which  have  not 
been  persistently  pressed  on  them  by  outside  agitation. 
The  House  of  Commons  itself  has  not  yet  outgrown  its 
traditional  attitude  of  a  court,  to  which  suitors  must  them- 
selves bring  petitions  if  they  desire  to  have  their  grievances 
remedied,  and  must  present  their  case  too,  in  certain  pre- 
scribed forms,  on  pain  of  seeing  it,  however  gross  the  evil, 
ignored  for  many  years.  The  result  is  that  the  Common 
Rules  necessary  to  secure  health  and  safety  in  particular 
trades  are  placed  on  the  Statute  Book,  not  according  to  the 
urgency  of  the  need,  or  the  extremity  of  the  evil,  but  accord- 
ing to  the  strength  of  the  pressure  which  is  brought  to  bear. 
In  many  individual  cases  this  pressure  has  come  from  the 
philanthropists.  The  agitations  which  led  to  the  prohibition 
of  the  use  of  "climbing  boys"  to  clean  chimneys  (I84O),1 

1  It  took  over  sixty  years'  agitation  to  complete  this  reform.  In  1817  a 
Select  Committee  exposed  the  horroi-s  to  which  the  "climbing  boy"  was  exposed. 
Legislation  followed  in  1834,  when  the  employment  of  boys  under  ten  was  for- 
bidden, and  it  was  made  a  criminal  offence  for  a  master  to  send  a  child  up  a 
chimney  when  it  was  actually  on  fire  !  This  caused  the  insurance  companies  to 
petition  against  the  measure.  In  1840  the  minimum  age  for  chimney-sweep 
apprentices  was  raised  to  sixteen,  and  a  formal  prohibition  of  their  being  com- 
pelled to  ascend  chimneys  was  embodied  in  the  law.  This  remained  largely 
ineffective  until,  in  1 864,  the  Chimney  Sweepers'  Regulation  Act  punished  with 
imprisonment  and  hard  labor  any  master  who  sent  a  boy  up  a  chimney.  The 
last  case  of  a  boy  dying  in  the  chimney — once  not  unusual — occurred  in  1875, 
when  another  Act  was  passed  increasing  the  stringency  of  the  law.  For  a  general 
survey  of  the  progress  in  this  protective  legislation,  see  The  Queen's  Reign  for 
Children,  by  W.  Clarke  Hall  (London,  1897). 


364  Trade  Union  Function 

and  of  the  employment  of  children  in  theatres  (1889), 
derived  their  force  from  the  ability  with  which  their  advo- 
cates appealed  to  middle-class  sentiment.  Similar  adroit 
management  accounts  for  Mr.  Plimsoll's  success  in  1876  in 
extending  the  Merchant  Shipping  Acts,  though  on  this  occa- 
sion the  political  influence  of  the  organised  Trade  Unions 
came  effectively  into  play.1  The  protective  rules  in  the 
Mines  Regulation  Acts  have,  on  the  other  hand,  been 
initiated  since  1843  by  the  Coalminers'  leaders  themselves, 
though  the  direct  influence  of  the  Mining  Unions  has  been 
aided  by  general  public  sympathy.  But  it  is  in  the  Common 
Rules  secured  by  the  Cotton  Operatives  that  we  see  the  most 
striking  result  of  Trade  Union  pressure.  The  Factory  Acts 
which  their  support  enabled  Mr.  Oastler  and  Lord  Shaftes- 
bury  to  carry  between  1833  and  1847  were  mainly  directed 
to  a  limitation  of  the  hours  of  labor.  Since  1870,  how- 
ever, the  ingenuity  and  persistence  of  the  cotton  officials 
have  greatly  extended  the  scope  of  the  legal  regulation  of 
their  trade.  The  elaborate  and  detailed  provisions  of  the 
law  as  to  stoppages  for  cleaning  and  protection  of  machinery, 
the  ventilation  of  the  mills,  and  the  exact  space  to  be  allowed 
between  the  fixed  and  moving  parts  of  the  mule,  the  regu- 
lation of  the  temperature  and  the  degree  of  humidity  in  the 
weaving-shed,  go  far  beyond  anything  that  Parliament  has 
yet  done  in  the  way  of  collective  regulation  of  the  conditions 
of  labor  in  the  factories  and  workshops  of  other  trades.2 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  p.  356. 

2  This  is  the  more  remarkable  in  that  cotton  manufacture  is  an  industry  in 
which  the  margin  of  profit  has  long  been  steadily  declining,  and  has,  according  to 
many  authorities,  now  almost  vanished.     Foreign  competition,  too,  is  admittedly 
keen  and  increasing.      On  the  other  hand,  the  wholesale  slop  clothing  trade  has, 
during  the  present  generation,  expanded  by  leaps  and  bounds,  and  has  notoriously 
produced  colossal  fortunes.     Yet  whilst  the  cotton  operatives  secure  from  Parlia- 
ment refinement  after  refinement  at  the  cost  of  their  employers,  the  unfortunate 
men  and  women  employed  by  the  wholesale  clothiers,  whose  woes  were  laid  bare 
by  the  House  of  Lords  Committee  on  the  Sweating  System,    1888-90,  are  still 
practically  excluded  from  the  protection  of  the  Factory  Inspector.     See   "  The 
Lords'  Report  on  the  Sweating  System,"  by  Beatrice  Potter,  Nineteenth  Century, 
Tune  1890  ;  and  Fabian  Tract  No.  50,  Sweating:  its  Cause  and  Remedy  (London, 
"i893)- 


Sanitation  and  Safety  365 

On  the  other  hand,  the  genuine  public  sympathy  with  the 
unfortunate  chain  and  nail  worker  in  the  Black  Country, 
with  the  London  "  fur  -puller  "  and  match-box  maker,  with 
the  laundress  or  the  dock-laborer,  has  resulted  in  nothing 
but  sham  legislation  of  an  entirely  illusory  character.1 
Experience  proves,  in  fact,  that  public  sympathy  with  the 
worker's  desire  for  Common  Rules  securing  safe  and  healthy 
conditions  of  work  leads  to  effective  regulation  only  when 
the  grievances,  besides  being  graphically  and  persistently 
pressed  on  the  House  of  Commons,  are  accompanied  by 
proposals  for  reform  which  have  been  worked  out  in  all  their 
technical  detail  by  practical  experts.  To  put  it  concretely, 
the  factory  legislation  which  each  trade  has  obtained,  has, 
during  the  last  twenty  years,  varied  in  stringency  and 
effectiveness,  not  according  to  the  misery  of  the  workers  or 
the  profitableness  of  the  enterprise,  but  almost  exactly  with 
the  amount  of  money  which  the  several  unions  have  expended 
on  official  and  legal  assistance. 

So  far  we  have  dealt  only  with  the  promotion  of  health 
or  safety  by  means  of  specific  regulations  prescribing  the 
conditions  which  experience  has  shown  to  be  necessary  to 
prevent  accident  or  disease.  In  one  direction,  however,  the 
Trade  Unionists  have  departed  from  this,  the  general  line  of 
their  policy,  and  have  sought  safety  in  imposing  upon  the 
employer,  not  positive  regulations  to  prevent  the  evil,  but  an 
obligation  to  pay  compensation  for  it  when  it  has  happened. 
This  leads  us  to  the  long  and  bitter  controversy  connected 
with  "  Employer's  Liability,"  in  which,  during  the  last  twenty 
years,  both  workmen  and  politicians  have  more  than  once 
shifted  their  ground.  To  understand  the  changing  features 
of  this  controversy,  we  must  examine,  in  some  detail,  both  its 
history  and  its  various  aspects.2 

1  On  the  futility  of  the  laundry  clause  in  the  Factory  Act  of  1895,  see  tne 
article,  "Law  and  the  Laundries,"  in  the  Nineteenth  Century,  December  1896, 
published  by  the  Industrial  Sub-Committee  of  the  National  Union  of  Women 
Workers. 

2  The  best  account  of  this  difficult  subject  is  the  Home  Office  Memorandum 
printed  as  Appendix  CLIX.  to  the  Labor  Commission  Blue  Book,   C.    7063, 


366  Trade  Union  Function 

By  the  common  law  of  England  a  person  is  liable,  not 
only  for  his  own  negligence,  but  for  that  of  his  servant  acting 
as  such.  It  does  not  appear  that  this  law  was,  in  old  times, 
made  use  of  by  workmen  against  their  employers — probably 
no  one  thought  of  such  an  insurrectionary  proceeding — but 
in  1837  an  action  (Priestley  v.  Fowler)  was  brought  against 
a  butcher  by  one  of  his  assistants  to  recover  compensation 
for  injuries  resulting  from  the  overloading  of  a  cart.  It  was 
proved  that  the  overloading  was  due  to  the  negligence  of  a 
fellow-servant.  On  this  ground  the  judges  decided  that  the 
injured  servant  could  not  recover  compensation  from  the 
common  employer.  This  decision  is  now  deemed  by  some 
scientific  jurists  to  have  been  bad  law  ; l  but,  good  or  bad,  it 
founded  the  distinction  which  has  ever  since  been  made 
between  strangers,  to  whom  the  employer  is  responsible  for 
the  negligence  of  his  servants,  and  the  servants  themselves. 

III.  A  (1894),  pp.  363,  384,  and  the  comments  by  Sir  F.  Pollock  in  the  same 
volume  (Appendix  clviii.  pp.  346-348),  with  Mr.  A.  Birrell's  Four  Lectures 
on  the  Law  of  Employers'  Liability  at  Home  and  Abroad  (London,  1897). 
The  Report  and  Evidence  of  the  Select  Committee  of  1887  (H.  C.  No.  285 
of  1887)  is  also  important.  For  a  more  detailed  and  technical  account  of 
the  law  and  its  development,  see  Employers  and  Employed,  by  W.  C.  Spens 
and  R.  F.  Younger  (London,  1887),  or  Duty  and  Liability  of  Employers,  by 
W.  H.  Roberts  and  G.  H.  Wallace  (London,  1885).  The  Trade  Union  view  is  well 
given  in  the  pamphlet  Employers'  Liability :  "  Past  and  Prospective  Legislation, 
with  Special  Reference  to  Contracting- Out,"  by  Edmond  Brown  (London,  1896). 
This  is  ably  criticised  in  the  Daily  Chronicle  pamphlet,  The  Workers'  Tragedy 
(London,  1897).  For  another  point  of  view,  see  Mr.  Chamberlain's  article  in 
the  Nineteenth  Century,  November  1892,  and  his  speeches  in  Parliament  during 
May  and  July  1897  ;  Miners'  Thrift  and  Employers'  Liability,  by  G.  L.  Campbell 
(Wigan,  1891) ;  and  Employers'  Liability:  What  it  Ought  to  Be,  by  Henry  W. 
Wolff  (London,  1897).  The  exhaustive  report  of  the  French  Government 
"Commission  de  Travail"  for  1892  contains  full  information  on  Continental 
legislation,  as  to  which  see  the  interesting  proceedings  of  the  International 
Congresses  on  Industrial  Accidents,  held  at  Paris,  1889,  Berne,  1891,  Milan, 
1894  (Brussels,  1897)  ;  Dr.  T.  Bodiker's  Die  Arbeiterversichentng  in  den 
Europdischen  Staaten  (Leipzig,  1895)  ;  and  the  elaborate  bibliography  published 
in  Circular  No.  I,  Series  B,  of  the  Musee  Social  (Paris,  1896). 

1  Sir  Frederick  Pollock  remarks,  in  the  Memorandum  already  cited,  "  I 
think  the  doctrine  of  the  American  and  English  Courts  (for  it  is  American  quite 
as  much  as  English)  is  bad  law  as  well  as  bad  policy.  The  correct  course,  in  my 
judgment,  would  have  been  to  hold  that  the  rule  expressed  by  the  maxim 
respondeat  superior,  whatever  its  origin  or  reason,  was  general.  .  .  .  No  such 
doctrine  as  that  of  common  employment  has  found  place  in  the  law  courts  of 
France  or  of  any  German  State." 


Sanitation  and  Safety  367 

The  lawyers  explained  that  the  workmen  must  be  held 
implicitly  to  have  contracted  to  take  upon  themselves,  as 
part  of  the  risk  incidental  to  their  calling,  the  possible  negli- 
gence of  fellow-employees,  for  whose  action,  therefore,  the 
common  employer  could  not  fairly  be  considered  liable. 

To  the  manual  worker  this  distinction,  for  which  Lord 
Abinger  was  chiefly  responsible,  seemed  an  intolerable  piece 
of  "  class  legislation."  The  workman,  injured  in  the  actual 
performance  of  his  duty,  was  at  least  as  fit  an  object  for 
compensation  as  the  chance  passer-by.  The  exception, 
moreover,  destroyed  all  real  responsibility  of  the  largest 
employers  even  for  their  own  negligence.  In  mines  and 
railways,  and  in  the  large  establishments  characteristic  of 
modern  industry,  the  legal  "  employer  "  was  seldom  present 
or  in  personal  direction  of  the  operations.  He  might  be 
guilty  of  the  grossest  carelessness  in  choosing  his  managers  ; 
he  might  not  provide  sufficient  means  for  proper  appliances  ; 
he  might  worry  his  agents  to  increase  the  speed  of  working, 
deliberately  bringing  pressure  to  bear  on  his  superintendents 
and  foremen  to  increase  the  output  or  lower  the  cost  of 
production,  to  the  hazard  of  the  lives  of  all  concerned.  Yet 
because  he  did  not  give  the  specific  order,  or  direct  the  use 
of  the  particular  machine,  out  of  which  the  accident  arose,,  he 
escaped  all  liability  for  compensation  to  his  injured  workmen, 
on  the  plea  that  the  negligence  was  that  of  their  fellow- 
worker,  the  manager  whom  he  had  put  in  authority  over 
them. 

Under  these  circumstances,  a  Trade  Union  agitation  for 
"  employers'  liability  "  was  sooner  or  later  inevitable.  It  was 
started  by  Alexander  Macdonald,  the  leader  of  the  coal- 
miners,  whose  remarkable  career  we  have  traced  in  our 
History  of  Trade  Unionism}  At  the  conference  of  miners' 
delegates  at  Ashton-under-Lyne  in  1858,  bitter  complaint 

1  See  the  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  284-292  ;  the  Report  of  the  Confer- 
ence of  the  National  Association  of  Coal,  Lime,  and  Ironstone  Miners  of  Great 
Britain  and  Ireland  [at  Leeds  in  1863]  (London,  1864) ;  Macdonald 's  speech  in 
the  similar  report  for  1881  (Manchester,  1881) ;  and  his  speech  in  Report  of  tke 
Eleventh  Annual  Trade  Union  Congress  (Bristol,  1878),  pp.  17,  18. 


368  Trade  Union  Function 

was  made  that  many  of  the  collieries  were  without  what 
would  now  be  considered  the  most  ordinary  safeguards  against 
accidents.  No  real  effort  was  made  by  the  Government  to 
enforce  the  merely  elementary  provisions  of  the  Mines 
Regulation  Act  of  1842.  The  frequent  mine  explosions 
which  marked  the  years  1860-67,  culminating  in  the  terrible 
catastrophes  at  the  Hartley,  Edmunds  Main,  and  Oaks 
Collieries,  where  hundreds  of  miners  lost  their  lives,  brought 
the  question  of  the  responsibility  of  the  employer  prominently 
to  the  front.  "  How  long  then,"  asked  the  miners  at  their  con- 
ference in  1863,"  shall  such  conduct  and  workings  be  tolerated  ? 
To  talk  of  humanity  is  nothing,  and  the  law  as  now  carried 
out  is  useless.  To  make  the  result  costly  is,  then,  the  only 
present  remedy.  .  .  .  When  men's  lives  are  held  to  be  sacred 
their  safety  will  be  looked  to  as  a  matter  of  vital  importance. 
At  present  we  ask  them  to  be  considered  costly,  and  com- 
pensation to  be  awarded  accordingly.  Many  are  alive  to 
costs  who  are  dead  to  all  higher  feeling,  and  these  should  be 
dealt  with  accordingly."  ]  It  is  easy  to  understand  the  miners' 
policy.  Their  industry  was  already  subject  to  elaborate 
Common  Rules,  which  were  steadily  increasing  in  number  and 
scope.  What  was  lacking,  in  the  absence  of  any  serious 
Government  inspection,  was  some  means  of  compelling  com- 
pliance with  the  rules.  Failure  to  observe  them  was  primd 
facie  evidence  of  negligence  on  the  part  of  the  manager  of 
the  mine.  If  the  Miners'  union  could  recover  damages  from 
the  mine-owner  whenever  an  accident  occurred  in  a  colliery 
where  the  law  had  not  been  obeyed,  the  risk  of  having  to  pay 
out  several  thousand  pounds  would,  it  was  argued,  induce  the 
employer  to  take  the  prescribed  precautions  against  accidents. 
The  proposed  right  of  the  operative  to  sue  an  employer  was 
merely  a  practical  method  of  enforcing  obedience  to  the 
Common  Rules  regulating  the  industry.  Thus,  to  Alexander 
Macdonald,  employers'  liability  presented  itself  only  as  one 
of  the  instruments  of  his  general  policy  of  obtaining  legal 

1   Transactions  and  Results  of  the  National  Association  of  Coal  etc.  Miners  of 
Great  Britain  (London,  1863),  pp.  x.-xiii. 


Sanitation  and  Safety  369 

protection    for    the    health    and    life    of    the     underground 
workers. 

This  argument  was  soon  reinforced  by  another.  In  1872 
the  proposal  was,  at  the  instance  of  the  newly-formed  Amal- 
gamated Association  of  Railway  Servants,  taken  up  by  the 
Trade  Union  Congress.  Inspired,  as  the  Congress  then  was, 
by  the  able  men  who  were  fighting  the  battle  for  the  work- 
men's freedom  of  association,  it  was  eager  to  denounce  all 
laws  which  excluded  manual  workers  from  the  personal 
rights  enjoyed  by  other  classes  of  the  community.  To  the 
Parliamentary  Committee  of  these  years  the  wage-earner's 
disability  to  recover  compensation  from  his  employer,  in  cases 
in  which  a  stranger  could  successfully  have  sued,  seemed 
another  of  the  invidious  disabilities  to  which  the  law  at  that 
time  subjected  workmen  as  such.  The  lawyer's  contention 
that  the  wage-earner,  by  entering  into  a  contract  of  service, 
had  placed  himself  in  a  position  different  from  that  of  the 
ordinary  citizen,  was  incomprehensible  to  them.  "There  seems 
to  be  no  sufficient  reason,"  declared  the  Parliamentary  Com- 
mittee in  1876,  "for  these  exceptions  to  the  general  law. 
Negligence  in  the  employer,  or  in  some  person  for  whose 
conduct  he  is  ordinarily  responsible,  and  whom  he  has  the 
power  to  dismiss,  must  of  course  be  shown.  But  if  that  is 
shown,  why  should  more  be  required  in  the  case  of  a  workman 
than  in  any  other  case.  The  present  state  of  the  law  takes 
away  a  motive  for  the  exercise  of  careful  control  and  super- 
vision by  the  employer.  It  even  makes  it  his  interest  not 
to  examine  too  minutely  into  the  way  in  which  his  work  is 
carried  on,  lest  he  should  be  held  to  have  personally  inter- 
fered, and  to  have  become  personally  liable.  The  proposed 
alteration  of  the  law  would  not  be  any  exceptional  legislation 
in  favor  of  workmen  :  it  would  be  merely  the  repeal  of  an 
exceptional  exclusion  of  them  from  the  ordinary  protection 
of  the  law."  l 

1  Parliamentary  Committee's   Report  to   the    Ninth   Annual    Trade    Union 
Congress,    i8th   September    1876,   pp.    3,  4  ;    see  History  of  Trade  Unionism, 
chap.  vii.      Between  1872  and  1879  no  fewer  than  eight  Employers'   Liability 
VOL.  I  2  B 


370  Trade  Union  Function 

The  energetic  agitation  between  1872  and  1880  was 
entirely  based  on  these  two  arguments.  Almost  every 
session  saw  the  matter  brought  before  Parliament  in  one 
form  or  another  ;  and  each  Ministry  in  succession  promised 
to  effect  an  amendment  of  the  law.  At  last,  in  1880,  by 
the  skill  and  persistence  of  Mr.  Broadhurst,  an  Employers' 
Liability  Act  was  passed,  which  went  far  to  meet  the  con- 
temporary Trade  Union  demands.  The  "  doctrine  of  common 
employment "  was  not  absolutely  abolished  ;  but  an  employer 
was  made  liable  to  compensate  his  injured  workmen  when- 
ever the  accident  resulted  from  the  negligence  of  any  super- 
intendent, manager,  or  foreman,  or  from  obedience  to  any 
improper  order  or  rule.  A  special  clause,  put  in  for  the 
benefit  of  railway  servants,  made  the  employer  responsible 
for  the  negligence  of  any  person  in  charge  of  railway  signals, 
points,  or  engine. 

Though  the  workmen  (and,  in  particular,  the  miners  and 
railway  servants)  thus  obtained  a  large  measure  of  the  reform 
they  had  demanded,  experience  soon  convinced  the  Trade 
Unionists  that,  even  to  the  extent  that  the  1880  Act  went, 
placing  the  workman  in  the  same  position  as  the  ordinary 
citizen  did  practically  nothing  to  secure  his  safety  from 
accident.  The  argument  that  the  wage-earner  ought  to  be 
placed,  as  regards  compensation  for  accidents,  in  the  same 
position  as  any  one  else,  led  also  to  the  conclusion  that  he 
should  be  free  to  enter  into  any  contract  as  to  his  legal  rights, 
whether  by  way  of  compromising  an  accident  already  suffered 
or  by  way  of  compounding,  in  advance,  for  any  possible  acci- 
dent in  the  future.  The  employers  accordingly  met  the  new 
Act  by  inventing  the  device  since  known  as  "  contracting  out." 

It  was  decided  in  1882,  in  Griffiths  v.  The  Earl  of 
Dudley,1  that  if  a  workman  continued  in  employment  after 
receipt  of  a  notice  that  he  must  forego  all  his  rights  under 

Bills  were  introduced  in  the  House  of  Commons  ;  see  the  interesting  pamphlet 
by  Mr.  C.  H.  Green,  Employers'  Liability:  Its  History,  Limitation,  and  Exten- 
sion (London,  1896),  written  by  an  insurance  official  from  an  insurance  point  of 
view. 

1  9  Queen's  Bench  Division,  357. 


Sanitation  and  Safety  371 

the  Act,  and  accept,  in  lieu  thereof,  a  claim  on  a  benefit 
club  to  which  the  employer  contributed,  he  was  held  to  have 
entered  into  a  contract  to  relinquish  the  rights  given  him  by 
the  Act  of  1880.  The  consequences  of  this  decision  were 
soon  apparent.  It  did  not  suit  a  large  employer  to  be 
exposed  to  the  risk  of  an  indefinite  liability,  or  to  the  worry 
of  being  sued  for  compensation  by  every  aggrieved  workman. 
It  became  a  custom  in  many  collieries,  and  in  some  railway 
and  other  large  undertakings,  to  establish  a  special  accident 
fund  or  benefit  society,  to  which  both  employer  and  workmen 
subscribed,  and  from  which  was  provided,  without  litigation 
substantial  relief  in  all  cases  of  accident,  whether  due  to 
proved  negligence  or  not.  This  enabled  the  partners  or 
shareholders  to  satisfy  their  moral  responsibilities  to  disabled 
workmen  at  the  least  possible  expense  and  trouble  to  them- 
selves, since  their  wage-earners  directly  contributed  a  portion 
of  the  fund,  and  the  total  amount  of  the  firm's  payment  was 
precisely  defined  in  advance.  Such  a  fund,  moreover,  tended 
to  attach  their  workmen  permanently  to  their  service  by  dis- 
posing them  to  abide  by  the  employer's  conditions,  rather 
than  forfeit,  by  going  elsewhere,  their  claims  on  the  firm's 
benefit  society.  Above  all,  the  existence  of  such  a  fund, 
providing  as  it  did  for  all  accidents  whatsoever,  enabled  the 
firm  confidently  to  insist  that  its  workmen  should  "contract 
out "  of  the  Employers'  Liability  Act,  and  thus  forego  the 
more  limited  but  legally  enforced  claims  for  compensation 
which  they  could  otherwise  make  under  it. 

The  vehemence  and  persistency  with  which  the  entire 
Trade  Union  world  has  protested  against  this  practice  of 
"  contracting  out "  has  all  through  been  incomprehensible  to 
the  middle-class  man.  To  him  the  whole  object  of  Em- 
ployers' Liability  is  compensation  to  the  injured  workman  or 
his  family.  If  by  a  special  accident  fund  this  compensation 
can  be  provided,  not  merely  for  some,  but  for  all  accidents 
whatsoever,  and  if,  moreover,  the  expense  of  litigation  can 
thereby  be  avoided,  it  seems  a  clear  gain  to  both  parties. 
What  the  middle-class  man  fails  to  realise  is  that  this  is  to 


372  Trade  Union  Function 

remit  the  all-important  question  of  safety  of  the  workman's 
life  to  the  perils  of  Individual  Bargaining.  The  Trade 
Unionists  assert  that  the  workman's  consent  to  forego  his 
legal  claim  is  given  practically  under  duress,  since  a  man 
applying  for  employment  has  no  free  option  whether  or  not  he 
will  join  the  firm's  benefit  society,  and  so  relieve  his  employer 
from  that  pecuniary  inducement  to  guard  against  accidents 
which  the  Act  was  intended  to  afford.  Moreover,  it  is  said 
that  this  inability  of  the  individual  workman  to  bargain 
about  the  conditions  of  his  employment  leads,  in  certain 
instances,  to  his  being  simply  defrauded,  the  benefit  of  the 
employer's  fund  being  inferior  to  what  he  could  obtain  by 
relying  on  the  Act  and  paying  his  contributions  to  an  ordi- 
nary friendly  society.  But  the  fundamental  Trade  Union 
objection  is  that  this  "  contracting  out,"  even  if  willingly 
acquiesced  in  by  each  individual  workman,  is  against  public 
policy,  as  defeating  the  primary  purpose  of  the  Act.  If  the 
employer,  they  say,  can  avoid  all  liability  for  negligence  by 
making  an  annual  contribution,  fixed  in  advance,  he  has  no 
inducement  to  take  precautions  against  individual  accidents. 
Macdonald's  idea  of  protecting  the  workman's  life  by  making 
accidents  costly  is,  in  fact,  thereby  entirely  defeated. 

For  the  last  fifteen  years  the  Trade  Union  leaders  have, 
therefore,  waged  bitter  war  against  "  contracting  out,"  1  and 
have  persistently  forced  upon  Parliament  their  demand  for 
an  express  prohibition  of  the  practice.  In  1893  the  Cabinet 
was  converted  to  the  Trade  Union  position.  Once  again  the 
Trade  Unionists  found  all  their  demands  embodied  in  a 
Government  Bill,  which  successfully  passed  the  House  of 
Commons.  An  amendment  was  inserted  by  the  House  of 
Lords  preserving  the  liberty  of  contracting  out  of  the  Act, 
but  under  certain  significant  new  safeguards.2  In  emphatic 
condemnation  of  the  practice  of  the  London  and  North- 

1  The  London  and  North- Western  Railway  Company,  and  all  but  one  of  the 
South-West  Lancashire  coalowners  at  present  (1897),  explicitly  compel  all  their 
operatives  to  "contract  out." 

2  The  House  of  Lords'  Amendment,  together  with  the  final  discussion  upon 
it,  will  be  found  in  Hansard's  Parliamentary  Debates,  I3th  February  1894. 


Sanitation  and  Safety  373 

Western  Railway  Company  and  the  Lancashire  Coalowners, 
the  House  of  Lords  declared  that  "  contracting  out "  was  in 
no  case  to  be  made  a  condition  of  the  workman's  being  given 
employment.  It  was  not  even  to  be  left  any  longer  to  Indi- 
vidual Bargaining.  No  "  contracting  out "  was  to  be  per- 
mitted unless  the  financial  basis  of  the  employer's  benefit 
society  had  been  approved  by  the  Board  of  Trade  as  fair  to 
the  workmen.  But  this  was  not  all.  No  "  contracting  out" 
was  to  be  allowed,  however  favorable  to  the  men  might  be 
the  consideration  offered,  unless  it  had  been  collectively  agreed 
to  by  the  workers  in  the  establishment  considered  as  a  whole. 
For  this  purpose,  elaborate  provision  was  proposed  for  a 
"  secret  ballot "  of  the  workers  to  be  taken  under  authority 
of  the  Board  of  Trade  at  intervals  of  not  less  than  three 
years  ;  and  a  two-thirds  majority  was  to  be  necessary  for 
consent.  Thus,  under  no  circumstances  was  it  to  be  within 
the  option  of  an  individual  wage-earner,  acting  as  an  indi- 
vidual, to  forego  his  legal  rights.  In  spite  of  this  remarkable 
concession  to  the  central  position  of  Trade  Unionism — the 
objection  to  Individual  Bargaining — the  majority  of  the 
House  of  Commons,  at  the  instance  of  its  working-men 
members,  preferred  to  abandon  the  Bill  rather  than  accept  an 
amendment  allowing  the  detested  contracting  out  under  any 
conditions  whatsoever.1 

The  controversy  has  now  been  narrowed  down  to  so  fine 
a  point  that  the  Trade  Union  leaders  may  any  day  get  from 

1  The  bitterness  with  which  the  Trade  Union  officials  object  to  "contracting 
out,"  and  the  underlying  reason  which  led  them  to  refuse  even  the  safeguarded 
provision  of  the  House  of  Lords'  Amendment,  are,  we  think,  connected  not  with 
"contracting  out"  as  such,  but  with  the  existence  of  employers'  benefit  societies. 
An  accident  fund  or  benefit  society,  confined  to  the  workmen  in  a  particular 
establishment,  is,  as  we  shall  see  in  our  chapter  on  "The  Implications  of  Trade 
Unionism,"  in  many  ways  inimical  to  Trade  Unionism.  Employers'  benefit 
societies  are  far  older  than  the  Act  of  1880,  and  exist  in  many  firms  which  do 
not  contract  out.  Moreover,  contracting  out  may  take  place,  as  in  the  South 
Wales  coalmines,  with  an  accident  fund  common  to  the  whole  area,  and  thus 
independent  of  any  one  employer.  Employers'  benefit  societies  cannot  therefore 
be  swept  away  by  a  side  wind.  If  public  opinion  is  to  be  led  to  agree  to  their 
prohibition,  this  must  come,  like  the  removal  of  other  deductions  from  wages,  by 
an  amendment  of  the  Truck  Acts. 


374  Trade  Union  Fimction 

one  party  or  the  other  the  legislation  they  desire.  We 
are,  however,  inclined  to  believe  that  just  as  they  were  dis- 
appointed with  the  Act  of  1880,  though  it  gave  them  prac- 
tically what  they  then  demanded,  so  they  will  find  equally 
unsatisfying  any  measure  on  the  lines  of  the  Bill  of  1893-94, 
about  which  they  were  so  enthusiastic.  The  fact  is  there  is 
no  reason  to  believe  that  the  mere  prohibition  of  "  contracting 
out "  will  do  anything  to  diminish  the  number  of  accidents. 
Attempts  have  been  made  to  prove  that  the  comparatively 
few  undertakings  in  which  contracting  out  prevails  have  a 
higher  percentage  of  accidents  than  those  in  which  the 
Act  applies.  But  no  statistical  evidence  yet  adduced 
on  the  subject  will  stand  examination.1  It  is  said,  for 
example,  that  in  Lancashire  and  Wales,  where  the  coal- 
miners  contract  out,  the  proportion  of  accidents  is  appreci- 
ably higher  than  in  Yorkshire  or  Northumberland,  where 
they  do  not.  But  this  was  the  case  also  before  the  Act 
of  1880:  moreover,  the  proportion  of  accidental  deaths 
to  persons  employed  seems  to  be  diminishing  more  rapidly 
in  Wales  and  Lancashire  than  in  Northumberland.  It  is 
even  gravely  argued  that  the  London  and  North -Western 
Railway  Company  has  eight  times  as  many  accidents  as  the 
Midland — as  if  nothing  turned  on  the  different  definitions  of 
an  accident !  The  truth  is,  there  is  no  such  difference  of 
pecuniary  interest  as  is  supposed  between  the  employer  who 
"  contracts  out,"  and  the  one  who  remains  subject  to  the  Act. 
In  the  vast  majority  of  cases  the  employer  does  not  take 
the  trouble  to  ask  his  workmen  to  bargain  away  their  legal 
rights  ;2  he  protects  himself  against  the  worry  of  litigation  by 
the  simpler  device  of  insurance.  On  payment  of  a  definite 
annual  premium  to  an  ordinary  insurance  company  he  is 
indemnified  against  any  loss  by  claims  under  the  Act,  the 

1  A  well-known  barrister,  who  has  been  engaged  in  between  three  and  four 
hundred  Employers'  Liability  cases,  almost  exclusively  on  the  side  of  the  workmen, 
informed  us  that  his  experience  has  convinced  him   that  the  legal  liability  for 
compensation  had  no  effect  whatever  in  preventing  accidents,  at  any  rate  in  coal- 
mining. 

2  Thus,  in    1891,  only   119,122  coalminers,  out  of  648,450,  had  contracted 


Sanitation  and  Safety  375 

company,  to  boot,  taking  all  the  trouble  off  his  hands.  The 
fear  of  damages  may  here  and  there  induce  a  small  master 
to  obey,  more  promptly  than  before,  the  factory  inspector's 
order  to  guard  a  driving  wheel  or  fence  a  lift  shaft.  But  in 
the  great  staple  industries,  insurance  against  accidents,  at  a 
rate  of  premium  which  is,  in  practice,  uniform  for  all  the 
firms  in  the  trade,  is  becoming  almost  as  much  a  matter  of 
course  as  insurance  against  fire.  Thus,  even  where  the  work- 
men retain  all  their  legal  rights,  the  employer  has  usually  no 
more  pecuniary  interest  in  preventing  accidents  than  he  has 
where  they  have  been  compelled  to  contract  out  of  the  Act. 
"  Contracting  out,"  with  its  accompanying  contribution  to  an 
employer's  benefit  society,  is,  in  fact,  itself  only  a  minor  form 
of  insurance. 

Insurance  stands,  therefore,  in  the  way  of  the  Trade 
Union  plan  of  preventing  accidents  by  making  them  costly. 
In  the  case  of  ships  at  sea,  this  fact  has  occasionally  led 
philanthropists  to  suggest  that  insurance  should  be  pro- 
hibited. But  insurance  is  merely  a  private  bargain,  often 
indeed  only  a  co-operative  arrangement  between  friends  ; 
and  no  such  prohibition  could  possibly  be  enforced.  Be- 
sides, insurance  is  itself  only  a  device  for  spreading  an 
occasional  lump  sum  payment  equally  over  a  number  of 
years  :  so  that  the  largest  establishments  prefer  to  be  their 
own  insurers.  Here  the  setting  aside  of  a  few  hundred 
pounds  a  year  to  form  a  fund  out  of  which  to  pay  compen- 
sation for  occasional  workmen's  accidents  is  a  flea-bite 
compared  with  the  cost  and  trouble  of  adopting  the  elab- 
orate precautions  that  might  totally  prevent  their  occurrence. 
This  brings  us  to  the  economic  centre  of  the  whole  argu- 
ment. What  has  been  discovered  is,  that  in  the  majority  of 
industries  it  costs  less,  whether  in  the  form  of  an  annual 

out,  the  practice  being  unknown  in  Northumberland,  Durham,  Yorkshire,  the 
Midlands,  and  Scotland.  Of  railway  companies,  only  the  London  and  North- 
Western  (compulsorily),  and  the  London,  Brighton,  and  South  Coast  (optionally), 
employ  this  expedient.  In  other  industries  we  know  only  very  few  cases— such 
as  Messrs.  Chance's  great  glass  works,  and  Mr.  Assheton  Smith's  Dinorwic  slate 
quarries — where  the  men  contract  out. 


376 


Trade  Union  Function 


premium  or  in  that  of  an  occasional  lump  sum  out  of  profits, 
to  compensate  for  accidents  than  to  prevent  them.1 

Considered  as  a  method  of  preventing  industrial  accidents, 
the  whole  system  of  employers'  liability  is  an  anachronism. 
When  Parliament  became  convinced  that  no  coal  mine  could 
be  safely  worked  without  a  second  shaft,  it  did  not  seek  to 
mend  matters  by  conceding  to  the  miners  a  right  of  recover- 
ing compensation  from  the  mine-owner  who  worked  without 
such  a  shaft.  What  happened  was  that  all  mine-owners 
were  peremptorily  ordered  to  have  a  second  shaft,  under 
penalty  of  heavy  fines  for  each  day's  neglect  to  comply  with 
the  law.  When  public  opinion  demanded  that  the  operatives 
in  a  crowded  factory  should  not  be  exposed  to  the  risk  of 
being  burnt  to  death,  the  House  of  Commons  never  thought 
of  removing  this  risk  by  any  process  of  compensation  ;  it 
commanded  every  mill-owner  to  provide  proper  fire-escapes, 
or  be  punished  by  the  police  magistrate.  This  is  the 
method  of  our  factory,  mines,  railways,  and  merchant  ship- 
ping Acts,  and  all  our  public  health  legislation.  "  Imagine, 
for  the  sake  of  illustration,"  wrote  Jevons  in  1887,  "that 
there  is  in  some  factory  a  piece  of  revolving  machinery 
which  is  likely  to  crush  to  death  any  person  carelessly 
approaching  it.  Here  is  a  palpable  evil  which  it  would  be 

1  Thus,  to  take  only  one  industry,  there  can  be  little  doubt  that  the  large 
number  of  accidents  to  railway  servants  (on  an  average,  over  forty  every  day, 
a  quarter  of  which  are  connected  with  moving  vehicles)  could,  as  regards 
shunters,  be  at  once  diminished  by  the  universal  adoption  of  such  appliances 
as  automatic  couplings ;  and  that  in  particular,  the  almost  daily  sacrifice  of 
platelayers  could  be  avoided  by  the  rigging-up  of  temporary  signals.  But  to 
adopt  such  precautions  throughout  the  extensive  English  railway  system  would 
be  extremely  expensive,  and  possibly  irksome. 

The  trifling  amount  of  the  premium  that  suffices  to  meet  all  compensation  and 
costs  under  the  Act  of  1880  is,  in  this  connection,  very  significant.  The  Iron 
Trades  Employers'  Association  covers  the  liability  of  firms  employing  28,000  men 
in  engineering  and  shipbuilding  by  a  premium  varying  from  fifteen  to  twenty- 
seven  pence  per  £100  paid  in  wages.  In  the  building  trade  it  is  four  shillings 
per  ^100.  In  Northumberland  and  Durham  the  coalowners  have  a  mutual  insur- 
ance association,  to  which  they  pay  annually  a  sum  sufficient  to  meet  all  damages 
and  costs  which  any  of  their  members  have  to  pay  under  the  Act  of  1 880.  Their 
total  payments  during  five  years  were  only  ^400  a  year,  a  sum  which  would  not 
have  gone  far  in  providing  any  safeguards  in  all  their  collieries.  See  Evidence 
before  Select  Committee  on  Employers'  Liability,  1887  (H-  C.  No.  285). 


Sanitation  and  Safety  377 

unquestionably  well  to  avert  by  some  means  or  other.  But 
by  what  means  ? "  And  he  concluded  that  there  was  one 
"  mode  of  solving  the  question,  which  is  as  simple  as  it  is 
effective.  The  law  may  command  that  dangerous  machinery 
shall  be  fenced  ;  and  the  executive  government  may  appoint 
inspectors  to  go  round  and  prosecute  such  owners  as  disobey 
the  law."  1 

This  sounds  simple ;  but  it  involves  two  troublesome 
preliminaries.  First,  an  elaborate  technical  investigation  to 
ascertain  exactly  what  practical  precautions  should  be 
adopted  ;  and,  second,  to  induce  a  capitalist  Parliament  to 
enforce  them  against  negligent  employers.  In  1872  the 
latter  condition  was  so  hopeless  that  the  Trade  Union 
leaders  of  that  day  could  see  nothing  for  it  but  to  fall  back 
on  the  indirect  method  of  making  accidents  costly  to  the 
employer.  But  public  opinion  has  made  a  prodigious  stride 
during  the  last  twenty  years.  Parliament  no  longer  refuses 
to  regulate,  in  minute  detail,  the  processes  of  particular 
industries.  Though  both  the  scope  and  the  administration 
of  our  industrial  legislation  still  leave  much  to  be  desired, 
it  now  takes  only  a  few  years'  agitation  for  a  group  of 
philanthropists  or  a  well -organised  Trade  Union  to  get 
embodied,  either  in  an  Act  of  Parliament  or  in  a  "  special 
rule  "  of  the  Home  Secretary,  any  well-considered  regulation 
for  promoting  health  or  safety  which  has  been  approved 
by  the  scientific  experts.  Meanwhile,  in  one  industry  after 
another,  the  inspection  necessary  for  the  enforcement  of  the 
law  is  steadily  becoming  a  reality.  By  the  Coal  Mines 
Regulation  Act  of  1887  the  miners  in  any  pit  are  enabled 
to  appoint  two  inspectors  of  their  own,  who  are  empowered 
to  inspect,  once  a  month,  every  part  of  the  workings,  and 
formally  to  record  their  report  upon  them.  In  1858  there 
were  only  eleven  Government  inspectors  of  mines,  all  told. 
By  1896  this  number  had  been  increased  to  thirty-nine 
(including  assistant  inspectors),  and  the  service  made  much 

1  The  State  in  Relation  to  Labour,  by  W.  S.  Jevons  (London,    1887),  pp. 
1-4. 


378  Trade  Union  Function 

more  efficient.  In  the  ten  years  1884-1893  over  four 
thousand  railway  workers  lost  their  lives  by  accidents  with- 
out the  Board  of  Trade  troubling  even  to  inquire  into  more 
than  a  dozen  of  the  cases  ;  now,  with  the  appointment  of  two 
railway  workers  as  assistant  inspectors,  about  half  the  fatal 
accidents  that  take  place  are  made  the  subject  of  elaborate 
official  investigation,  with  a  view  of  suggesting  precautions 
to  prevent  their  recurrence.1  In  short,  the  protection  of 
the  worker  against  industrial  accidents  has  now  become  part 
of  the  acknowledged  work  of  Government.  An  avoidable 
casualty  in  a  factory  or  a  mine  is  no  longer  regarded  merely 
as  an  injury  to  the  individual,  to  be  atoned  for  by  the  pay- 
ment of  money  compensation  :  under  modern  legislation  it  is 
an  offence  against  the  community  punishable  by  the  magistrate. 
From  this  public  obligation  to  provide  for  health  and  safety 
there  can  obviously  be  no  "contracting  out."  Nor  is  it 
possible  for  the  employer  to  evade  his  liability  by  any 
payment  to  an  insurance  company.  The  inspector  and  the 
magistrate  are  empowered  to  see,  not  only  that  the  fine  is 
paid,  but  also  that  the  law  is  complied  with.  The  idea  of 
relying  for  the  protection  of  life  and  health  upon  the  chance 
activity  of  interested  plaintiffs  in  search  of  personal  compen- 
sation, seems,  to  the  modern  jurist,  archaic.  Like  murder, 
theft,  and  embezzlement,  the  unnecessary  risking  of  the 
workers'  lives  has  passed  from  the  domain  of  civil  to  that  of 
criminal  law. 

Let  us  now  leave  the  arguments  used  in  support  of 
employers'  liability  by  the  Trade  Union  officials,  and  con- 
sider why  it  secures  the  suffrages  of  the  rank  and  file. 
What  the  individual  workman  sees  in  the  proposal  is,  not 
so  much  a  vague  chance  of  lessening  the  risk  of  accidents, 
as  the  certainty  of  a  lump  sum  down  when  one  occurs,  to 
enable  him  or  his  widow  to  set  up  a  little  shop.  To  the 
miner  or  the  railway  servant  it  seems  an  intolerable  hardship 
that  his  family  should  be  reduced  to  beggary  through  no 

1  Report  of  General  Secretary  to  Annual  General  Meeting  of  the   Gtneral 
Railway  Workers'  Union  (London,  1897),  pp.  12- 1 7. 


Sanitation  and  Safety  379 

fault  of  his  own.  What  he  wants  is,  not  to  find  out  whose 
fault  the  accident  is — as  likely  as  not  it  is  nobody's  fault — 
but  to  be  compensated  for  his  misfortune.  That  is  also  the 
concern  of  the  community,  which  has  an  admitted  interest  in 
fulfilling  for  him  that  "  established  expectation  "  upon  which 
foresight  and  deHberateness  in  life  depend.  Here  all  inquiries 
as  to  whether  the  accident  is  caused  by  the  personal  negligence 
of  the  manager  or  the  carelessness  of  a  fellow-workman,  or 
whether  it  is  the  result  of  a  fog  or  an  inexplicable  explosion, 
are  quite  beside  the  question.  Whether  from  the  standpoint 
of  the  community  or  from  that  of  the  injured  workman,  the 
notion  of  making  compensation  in  any  way  dependent  on 
such  considerations  is  pure  inconsequence.  Accordingly, 
wherever  the  community  itself  undertakes  public  services,  it 
is  every  day  compensating  more  equitably  those  who  suffer 
bodily  injury  in  the  performance  of  their  duties.  In  the 
army  and  navy,  the  Civil  Service,  and  the  police,  in  the  Fire 
Brigade,  and  other  branches  of  municipal  administration, 
though  the  treatment  of  weekly  wage-earners  is  still  far  from 
being  as  favorable  as  that  of  salaried  officers,  we  see  con- 
stantly a  fuller  acceptance  and  more  generous  interpretation 
of  their  right  to  compensation.  Private  individuals  and 
corporations  sometimes  show  a  sense  of  the  same  responsi- 
bility. In  many  particular  instances  large  industrial  under- 
takings will  give  a  "  light  job,"  or  even  a  pension,  to  a  clerk 
or  workman  disabled  in  their  service.  Whenever  a  sensa- 
tional accident  occurs  at  sea  or  in  the  mine,  subscriptions 
pour  in  to  save  the  sufferers  or  their  widows  and  orphans 
from  the  workhouse.  In  short,  in  all  those  cases  in  which 
public  opinion  can  now  be  directly  appealed  to,  it  is  found 
to  be  largely  in  agreement  with  the  workman  that  it  is 
intolerable  for  his  livelihood  to  be  cut  short  through  no 
shortcoming  or  fault  in  his  own  character  or  conduct. 

We  have  said  above,  parenthetically,  that  an  accident  is 
as  likely  as  not  to  be  nobody's  fault.  It  is  necessary  to 
emphasise  this,  because  most  accidents  are,  to  use  the 
traditional  phrase  of  the  bill  of  lading,  "  the  act  of  God." 


380  Trade  Union  Function 

In  the  great  majority  of  industrial  casualties — probably  in 
three  cases  out  of  four — it  is  impossible  to  prove  that  the 
calamity  has  been  due  to  neglect  on  any  one's  part.  A  flash 
of  lightning  or  a  storm  at  sea,  a  flood  or  a  tornado,  irre- 
sponsibly claim  their  victims.  The  greatest  possible  care  in 
buying  materials  or  plant  will  leave  undiscovered  hidden 
flaws  which  one  day  result  in  a  calamity.  In  other  cases, 
the  accident  itself  destroys  all  trace  of  its  own  cause.  In 
many,  perhaps  in  most,  of  the  casualties  of  the  ocean  or  the 
mine,  the  shunting  yard  or  the  mill,  the  difficulties  in  the 
way  of  bringing  home  actual  negligence  to  any  particular 
person  are  insuperable.1 

Here,  then,  we  discover  a  fundamental  objection  to  the 
doctrine  of  employers'  liability — its  irrelevance  to  the  issue 
between  the  community  and  the  injured  workman,  and  its 
practical  inapplicability,  even  as  an  arbitrary  makeshift,  to 
most  of  the  cases  it  is  aimed  at.  Actual  experience  indi- 
cates that  it  neither  prevents  accidents,  nor  insures  their 
victims.  And  it  has  the  further  drawback  that  to  compel 
the  workman  to  extract  his  compensation  from  the  employer 
is  inevitably  to  plunge  him  into  litigation.  Even  where 
compensation  can  now  be  recovered  the  law  costs  are  a 
serious  evil.  Moreover,  unless  the  sufferer  happens  to 
belong  to  a  strong  and  wealthy  Trade  Union,  which  takes 
his  case  up,  it  is  usually  quite  impossible  for  him  to  fight 
it  at  all,  from  lack  of  both  knowledge  and  funds  ;  so  that  he 
is  practically  driven  to  accept  any  compromise  offered  by  the 
employer.  The  Home  Office  itself  admits  the  failure.  In 

1  The  proportion  of  industrial  accidents  for  which  actual  or  constructive 
negligence  by  the  employer  can  be  shown  has  been  variously  estimated  at  from 
one-tenth  to  one-half  of  the  whole.  The  Employers'  Liability  Assurance  Cor- 
poration,  which  insures  employers  against  their  liability  under  the  Act  of  1880, 
found  that,  in  this  class  of  policies,  claims  were  made  on  them  for  only  24  per 
cent  of  the  accidents  reported  ;  and  estimated  that,  in  another  class  of  policies, 
where  all  accidents  whatsoever  were  insured  against,  only  3026  out  of  26,087 
admitted  claims  (or  less  than  one-eighth)  represented  accidents  for  which  the 
employer  might  have  been  held  legally  liable.  See  evidence  before  Select  Com- 
mittee  on  Employers'  Liability,  1887  (H.  C.  No.  285),  pp.  4165-4308,  and 
Appendices. 


Sanitation  and  Safety  381 

its  official  memorandum  on  the  state  of  the  law  it  goes  so 
far  as  to  say,  "  the  truth  is  that  to  the  workman  litigation 
under  the  Act  of  1880  has  more  than  its  usual  terrors.  It 
is  not  merely  that  litigation  is  expensive,  and  that  he  is  a 
poor  man  and  his  employer  comparatively  a  rich  one :  it 
is  that  when  a  workman  goes  to  law  with  his  employer,  he, 
as  it  were,  declares  war  against  the  person  on  whom  his 
future  probably  depends  ;  he  seeks  to  compel  him  by  legal 
force  to  pay  money ;  and  his  only  mode  of  doing  so  is  the 
odious  one  of  proving  that  his  employer  or  his  agents — his 
own  fellow -work  men — have  been  guilty  of  negligence." 
Finally,  such  migratory  workers  as  seamen  find  legal 
remedies  against  their  employers  absolutely  illusory,  owing 
to  the  impossibility  of  collecting  and  keeping  together  their 
witnesses,  if  these  are  fellow-seamen,  during  the  law's  delays. 

Let  us  now  examine  the  question  from  the  employer's 
point  of  view.  Why  should  he  bear  the  cost  of  an  accident 
which  is  the  "  act  of  God,"  merely  because  it  happens  to 
have  occurred  on  his  premises,  especially  when  the  same 
unavoidable  calamity  which  has  injured  his  employees  may 
have  crippled,  or  even  ruined,  his  own  business  ?  And  even 
in  the  case  of  accidents  due  to  his  own  neglect,  how  can  any 
proportion  be  depended  on  between  the  degree  of  his  culp- 
ability and  the  penalty  of  adequately  providing  for  all  the 
sufferers  ?  One  accident  may  involve  the  payment  of  a  five- 
pound  note  to  a  man  who  has  been  laid  up  for  a  week  with 
a  scalded  hand  :  an  exactly  similar  accident,  caused  in  an 
exactly  similar  way,  may  kill  or  disable  for  life  a  score  of 
people.  The  most  criminal  negligence  may  lead  only  to  a 
breakdown  which  hurts  nobody,  whilst  a  very  venial  over- 
sight may  make  an  employer  liable  to  fabulous  compensa- 
tion. Thus  there  is  injustice  in  making  him  liable  for 
avoidable  accidents,  and  no  justice  at  all — no  sense,  in  fact 
— in  making  him  liable  for  unavoidable  ones.  Is  it  to  be 
wondered  at  that  employers  resolutely  resist  Liability  Bills 
in  Parliament  without  regard  to  party  exigencies  ? 

We    now   see   why   the    provisions    of   the    Employers' 


382  Trade  Union  Function 

Liability  Act  of  1880,  like  those  of  the  score  of  Bills  which 
have  since  been  introduced  for  its  amendment,  are  inadequate 
and  even  illusory.  It  was,  no  doubt,  pleasant  to  get,  under 
the  Act,  some  pecuniary  compensation  for  a  comparatively 
small  class  of  cases,  which  would  otherwise  have  remained 
unprovided  for.  It  would  no  doubt  have  been  a  boon  to  a 
larger  number  of  sufferers  if  the  Bill  of  1893-94  had  been 
passed.  But  such  measures,  however  useful  they  may  be  to 
particular  sections  of  wage-earners,  deal  only  with  a  small 
proportion  of  the  cases  of  hardship,  and  do  not  discriminate 
in  their  favor  on  any  logical  or  permanently  tenable  ground. 
Abandoning,  then,  the  idea  that  systematic  provision  for 
the  sufferers  from  industrial  accidents  can  be  got  out  of 
any  possible  penalties  for  negligence,  however  widely  the 
lawyers  may  stretch  the  term,  what  shall  we  say  to  the 
suggestion,  as  yet  scarcely  whispered  by  Trade  Unionists, 
that  the  law  should  be  so  extended  as  to  make  provision  for 
sufferers  from  all  industrial  accidents,  whether  due  to  the 
proved  negligence  of  any  superior  or  not.  Both  in  Germany 
and  Austria  this  idea  has  been  already  embodied  in  elaborate 
schemes  of  universal  provision  for  accidents,  which  rank 
among  the  most  remarkable  of  social  experiments.  In 
England  the  proposal  has  appeared  as  a  natural  outcome  of 
the  Trade  Union  idea  of  maintaining  the  continuity  of  the 
worker's  livelihood.  At  the  Trade  Union  Congress  of  1877, 
universal  provision  for  all  industrial  accidents,  the  funds  to 
be  provided  by  a  tax  on  commodities,  was  suggested  by  a 
London  compositor,  as  an  alternative  to  the  usual  employers' 
liability  resolution.  It  was  vehemently  denounced  by 
Thomas  Halliday,  a  leader  of  the  coalminers,  who  said 
"  they  wanted  no  tax  upon  coal.  What  they  wanted  was 
that  their  lives  and  their  bodies  should  be  preserved.  The 
best  way  to  secure  this  was  to  make  the  employers  re- 
sponsible,, and  make  them  pay  the  cost.  What  they 
wanted  was  not  money,  but  their  lives  and  limbs  preserved." 
This  view  was  endorsed  by  Alexander  Macdonald  and 
accepted  by  the  Congress  amid  loud  cheers.  Thus,  the 


Sanitation  and  Safety  383 

rooted  belief  in  employers'  liability  as  a  means  of  preventing 
accidents,  coupled,  perhaps,  with  the  fear  of  a  deduction  from 
wages  for  compulsory  insurance,  brushed  aside  a  proposal 
which  deserved  more  careful  consideration.  By  it  we  are, 
indeed,  taken  outside  the  domain  of  anything  that  can  be 
called  employers'  liability,  however  much  the  phrase  may 
be  strained.  This  involves  a  reconsideration  of  the  incidence 
of  the  burden.  To  compel  employers  to  incur  the  liability 
implied  by  adequate  compensation  for  all  accidents  what- 
soever, would,  whether  done  directly  or  by  insurance,  involve 
a  serious  burden  upon  every  enterprise,  which  would  certainly 
be  shifted,  though  not  without  friction  and  expense,  on  to 
the  customers,  in  the  form  of  higher  prices.  What  is  more, 
it  would  fall  unequally  upon  different  industries  according  to 
their  risk,  and  would  thus  be  transferred  unequally  to  different 
classes  of  consumers,  not  at  all  in  proportion  to  their  ability 
to  bear  this  new  burden,  but  partly  at  haphazard,  partly  in 
proportion  to  their  actual  consumption.  At  every  "  reper- 
cussion "  of  the  tax,  there  would  be  an  additional  "  loading," 
so  that  the  ultimate  charge  on  the  consumer  would,  as  in 
the  case  of  excise  duties  on  raw  materials,  far  exceed  the 
original  sum.  As  soon  as  public  opinion  is  prepared  to 
decide  that  all  accidents  ought  to  be  compensated  for,  it 
will  be  at  once  easier,  fairer,  and  more  economical  to  provide 
the  necessary  annual  sum  from  public  funds,  and  to  raise  a 
corresponding  revenue  in  accordance  with  the  recognised 
canons  of  taxation. 

Upon  the  question  likely  to  interest  politicians — how 
soon  public  opinion  will  arrive  at  such  a  point — all  that  can 
be  said  is  that  the  electors  are  rapidly  becoming  aware  that 
accidents  are  an  inevitable  part  of  the  cost  of  modern 
industry ;  indeed,  statistically  considered,  they  are  not 
accidents  at  all,  but  certainties.  And,  as  we  have  seen,  the 
public  conscience,  which  has  never  been  perfectly  easy  on 
the  subject — how  could  it  be  in  a  great  mining,  manufac- 
turing, and  seafaring  community  like  ours  ? — grows  per- 
ceptibly more  sensitive  from  decade  to  decade.  The  question 


384  Trade  Union  Function 

cannot  be  let  alone :  some  solution  must  be  found.  At 
present  what  stands  most  conspicuously  in  the  way  of 
public  provision  for  all  sufferers  from  accidents,  coupled 
with  factory  legislation  for  their  prevention,  and  criminal 
prosecutions  for  the  punishment  of  negligence,  is  the 
belief  in  Employers'  Liability.  And  Employers'  Liability, 
as  we  have  seen,  breaks  down  at  every  point.  The  con- 
clusion is  obvious. 

It  would  be  an  incidental,  but  very  advantageous,  result 
of  any  scheme  of  public  provision  that  every  accident  would 
have  its  inquest.  There  would  be  many  gains  in  extending 
the  present  system  of  public  inquiry  into  casualties.  Such 
an  inquiry  is  now  held,  (a)  by  the  coroner,  if  death  .has 
resulted,  or  (in  the  City  of  London)  if  there  has  been  a  fire ; 
(b)  by  an  officer  of  the  Board  of  Trade,  in  cases  where  a 
ship  has  been  wrecked  or  a  railway  accident  involving 
injury  to  passengers  has  occurred  ;  and  (c)  by  an  officer  of 
the  Home  Office  in  mining  accidents.  Industrial  accidents 
of  every  kind  must  at  least  be  notified  to  a  public  office. 
If  a  public  "  inquest "  were  held,  by  a  duly  qualified  public 
officer  (with  or  without  a  jury),  whenever  an  accident  caused 
loss  of  life  or  limb,  or  other  serious  bodily  harm,  to  a 
wage-earner  in  the  course  of  his  employment,  the  investi- 
gation and  publicity  would  probably  do  much  to  secure 
compliance  with  the  Factory  or  Mines  Regulation  Acts, 
and  so  diminish  the  number  of  accidents.  If  any  system 
of  public  provision  for  the  sufferers  were  established,  such 
an  inquest  would  serve  a  useful  purpose  in  determining 
whether  a  casualty  had  been  caused  by  somebody's  negli- 
gence or  by  carelessness  on  the  part  of  the  sufferer  himself, 
or  whether  it  was,  in  the  strict  sense,  an  accident.  Where 
the  casualty  had  arisen  from  the  employer's  failure  to 
comply  with  the  law,  or  from  any  other  gross  negligence,  a 
criminal  prosecution  would  naturally  follow,  any  fine  im- 
posed thus  indirectly  reimbursing  the  State  for  the  expense 
caused.  When  the  sufferer  himself  had,  by  carelessness, 
brought  about  his  own  calamity,  his  compensation  could  be 


Sanitation  and  Safety  385 

wholly  or  in  part  withheld,  though  if  death  had  ensued 
there  would  be  no  public  advantage  in  making  his  widow 
and  orphans  go  short  of  necessary  maintenance.  The 
compensation  itself  should  in  all  cases  be  payable  by  the 
Government  out  of  public  funds.  Whether  there  is  any 
practical  advantage  in  the  Government,  as  in  Germany 
and  Austria,  then  levying  the  amount  on  corporations  of 
employers  (and  through  them  upon  the  consumers  and  wage- 
earners),  instead  of  directly  upon  the  taxpayers  as  such, 
seems  to  us  extremely  doubtful.  Such  a  system  of  finance 
contravenes,  like  an  excise  duty  on  raw  materials,  all 
the  orthodox  canons  of  taxation.  It  is  perhaps  more  to 
the  point  to  say  that  any  attempt  to  levy  an  insurance 
premium  upon  the  workman's  weekly  wage  would,  in 
this  country,  encounter  the  unrelenting  opposition  of  the 
whole  Trade  Union  and  friendly  society  world.1 

If  now  we  look  back  on  the  whole  Trade  Union  argu- 
ment from  the  workman's  point  of  view,  it  is  easy,  we  think, 
to  see  running  through  it  one  simple  idea.  Whether  we 
study  the  regulations  imposed  by  the  Collective  Bargaining 
of  the  iron  and  building  trades,  or  the  elaborate  technical 
provisions  of  the  Factory,  Mines,  and  Merchant  Shipping 
Acts ;  whether  we  disentangle  the  complicated  issues  of 
"  common  employment "  or  those  of  "  contracting  out,"  we 
always  strike  the  same  root  principle,  a  resolute  protest  by 
the  manual  worker  against  being  required  to  sell  his  life  or 
health,  in  a3ctftioTr-to  his  labor.  The  individual  wage-earner 
knows  that  he  may  always  be  bribed  or  terrorised  into 
accepting  conditions  of  employment  injurious  to  health  or 
dangerous  to  life  or  limb.  He  therefore  seeks,  through  his 
Trade  Union,  to  prohibit  Individual  Bargaining  on  these 
points,  and  to  enforce,  in  all  establishments,  those  conditions 
of  employment  which  experience  has  shown  to  be  necessary 
for  sanitation  and  safety.  It  is  in  vain  that  the  economists 

1  See,  on  this  point,  the  significant  Minority  Report  by  Mr.  Henry  Broadhurst, 
M.P.,  in  the  Report  of  the  Royal  Commission  on  the  Aged  Poor,  1893-95,  C. 
7684,  p.  xcviii. 

VOL.  I  2  C 


386  Trade  Union  Function 

have  assured  him  that  extra  risks  bring  higher  wages  ;  or 
the  employers  offered  him  liberal  inducements  in  return 
for  "  contracting  out "  of  protective  legislation.  What  the 
Trade  Unionist  has,  for  a  whole  generation,  uniformly 
answered,  is  that  he  will  not  "  coin  his  blood  for  drachmas." 
Hence  his  persistent  hankering  after  Common  Rules,  which 
shall  definitely  prescribe  how  much  cubic  space  shall  be 
allowed,  what  safeguards  against  accidents  shall  be  adopted, 
and  what  provisions  shall  be  made  for  protection  against 
disease  and  discomfort.  What  is  remarkable  is  that,  in 
this  resolute  determination  to  lift  out  of  the  sphere  of 
"personal  freedom"  the  option  to  suffer  disease,  maiming, 
or  death,  public  opinion  has  emphatically  endorsed  the 
Trade  Union  view.  It  is  no  longer  permitted  to  the  sailor 
to  decide  whether  he  will,  for  extra  wages,  accept  the  risk 
of  going  to  sea  in  an  overloaded  ship,  or  to  the  cotton 
operative  whether,  in  order  to  get  employment  at  all,  he  will 
put  up  with  a  weaving-shed  dripping  with  steam.  We  do 
not  now  leave  it  to  the  white  lead  worker  or  the  enameller  to 
bargain  with  their  employers  as  to  the  extent  to  which  they 
will  risk  their  health  by  dispensing  with  costly  precautions  ; 
or  allow  the  coalminer  the  option  of  earning  high  wages 
by  foregoing  the  elaborate  ventilation  of  an  exceptionally 
perilous  pit.  And  it  is  not  only  in  the  ever -lengthening 
Factory,  Mines,  Railways,  and  Merchant  Shipping  Acts  that 
this  conversion  of  the  public  is  apparent.  The  Employers' 
Liability  Act  of  1880  was  itself  a  proof  that  Parliament 
overrode  the  lawyers'  contention  that  the  workmen  must  im- 
plicitly accept,  as  part  of  the  wage  contract,  whatever  risk  to 
life  or  health  was  incidental  to  their  industry.  When,  in 
order  to  evade  this  law,  employers  invented  the  device  of 
"  contracting  out,"  a  Liberal  House  of  Commons  decided 
actually  to  prohibit  the  risk  of  accident  being  made  a  matter 
of  contract  at  all,  whilst  even  the  Conservative  House  of 
Lords  resolved  that  under  no  circumstances  could  it  be  left 
to  Individual  Bargaining.  Finally,  the  slackness  which  has 
now  come  over  the  whole  controversy  of  Employers' 


Sanitation  and  Safety  387 

Liability  is,  we  think,  to  be  attributed  largely  to  a  half- 
conscious  appreciation  by  the  public  that  the  mere  making 
of  accidents  costly — a  liability  which  can  always  be  insured 
against — is  not  the  way  to  prevent  them,  and  that  to  foist 
an  illusory  liability  on  the  employer  for  constructive  negli- 
gence is  not  the  way  to  provide  for  the  sufferers.  As  far  as 
the  United  Kingdom  is  concerned,  the  practical  conclusion  is 
to  prescribe,  by  definite  technical  regulations,  the  precautions 
against  accident  and  disease  which  experience  and  science 
prove  to  be  necessary ;  to  punish  any  breach  of  these 
regulations  whether  any  accident  has  happened  or  not ;  to 
hold  a  public  inquiry  into  every  serious  case  of  accident, 
and  (as  part  of  the  punishment)  make  the  employer  pay  a 
forfeit  to  the  State  according  to  the  degree  of  his  guilt, 
whenever  the  accident  has  resulted  from  any  breach  of  the 
rules  or  other  clear  negligence  ;  and  to  provide  from  public 
funds  for  the  injured  workman  and  his  family,  however  the 
accident  has  happened,  according  to  the  extent  of  their 
needs. 


The  foregoing  analysis  of  the  Trade  Union  controversy 
upon  Employers'  Liability  was  written  in  August  1896,  and 
published  in  January  iSp?.1  Since  that  date  the  whole 
situation  has  been  changed  by  the  introduction  and  passage 
into  law  of  Mr.  Chamberlain's  revolutionary  "  Workmen's 
Compensation  Bill."  This  measure  is  admittedly  no  final 
solution  of  the  problem,  and  we  prefer,  therefore,  to  leave 
intact  our  detailed  examination  of  the  position  in  which  the 
controversy  stood  in  1896,  rather  than  attempt  a  hasty 
reconstruction  on  the  basis  of  an  Act  as  yet  untested  by 
experience. 

The  measure  which  the  Conservative  Government  of 
1897  has  passed  as  an  alternative  to  the  Liberal  Govern- 

1  Progressive  Review. 


388  Trade  Union  Function 

ment's  proposal  of  1893-94,  seems,  in  an  almost  dramatic 
manner,   to   give    the   go-by   to   all   the   old    controversies.1 
Instead  of  quibbling  over  the  degree  to  which  the  employer's 
liability  for  negligence  can  be  stretched,  the  new  law  makes 
him,  in  most  of  the  great  industries  of  the  country,  individ- 
ually liable  to  compensate    his  workmen    for   all    accidents 
suffered  by  them  in  the  course  of  their  employment,  whether 
caused    by    negligence    or    not.       Thus,    without    expressly 
abolishing  the  doctrine  of  "  common  employment,"  the  law, 
by  securing  a  certain  limited  compensation  for  every  acci- 
dent whatsoever,  now  puts  the  workman  in  an  altogether 
different  position  from  the  injured  stranger,  who  can  claim 
only  in  case  of  the  employer's  real  or  constructive  negligence. 
And    although   "contracting   out"    is   nominally   permitted, 
provided  that  the  scheme  is  certified  by  the  Chief  Registrar 
of  Friendly    Societies   as    being    not    less  favorable  to  the 
workman  than  his  position   under  the  Act,  so  wide  is  now 
the  scope  of  the  law  and  so  stringently  is  this  exception 
guarded,  that  most  of  its  attractiveness  to  the  employer  will 
have  disappeared.     The  Trade   Unionists  were,  accordingly, 
well  advised  in   accepting  Mr.  Chamberlain's  bill,  notwith- 
standing its  limitations  and  defects.     The  right  to  compen- 
sation for  all  accidents,  now  granted  to  about  a  third  of  the 
manual  workers,  cannot  permanently  be  withheld  from  the 
other  two-thirds,  and  the  numerous  flaws  that  will  certainly 
manifest   themselves    in    the   working   of  so    novel   and   so 
far-reaching    a    statute,    may    be    confidently    left    to    the 
amending  bills  to  which  one  Government  after  another  will 
find  itself  committed. 

The  particular  employers  upon  whom  the  new  law  im- 
poses a  large  and  indefinite  pecuniary  liability  have,  we 
think,  a  real  grievance.  Certain  industries  have  been  thus 
burdened,  whilst  others,  no  less  liable  to  accidents,2  have 

1  For  a  bitter  attack  on  this  measure  from  the  Conservative  employer's  point 
of  view,  see  J.  Buckingham  Pope's  Conservatives  or  Socialists  (London,  1897). 

2  Besides  all  the  processes  of  agriculture,  the  building  or  repairing  of  houses 
less  than  30  feet  high,  and  all  workshop  industries,  the  Act  excludes  seamen  and 


Sanitation  and  Safety  389 

been  left  free.  Even  within  the  bounds  of  a  single  trade, 
establishments  using  one  process  are  made  liable  to  pay 
compensation  for  casualties  which  no  care  or  precaution 
could  prevent,  whilst  others,  using  a  different  process,  escape 
any  but  the  illusory  liability  of  the  old  law.  The  novel 
penalty  for  accidents  to  which  some  employers  are  thus 
subjected  bears  no  relation  to  the  degree  of  their  guilt  in 
trying  to  prevent  them  ;  a  casualty  due  exclusively  to  the 
"  act  of  God  "  will  cost  them  no  less  than  one  due  to  their 
own  personal  negligence.  In  practice  the  liability  to  com- 
pensation is  simply  insured  against,  and  employers  within 
the  scope  of  the  new  Act  find  themselves  saddled  with  an 
extra  insurance  premium,  constituting  an  addition  to  the 
cost  of  production  from  which  other  capitalists  are  exempt. 

The  two- thirds  of  the  manual  workers  whom  the  Act 
now  excludes  are  suffering  from  an  injustice  which  can- 
not easily  be  redressed  on  the  lines  of  the  present  law. 
It  may  be  practicable  to  put  a  liability  to  pay  com- 
pensation for  all  accidents  upon  a  railway  company,  a 
coalowner,  or  the  registered  occupier  of  a  steam  factory. 
Even  in  these  cases,  if  the  employer  neglects  to  insure, 
the  sufferers  in  an  extensive  accident  may  sometimes  find 
their  claims  baulked  by  the  firm's  bankruptcy.  But  a  large 
proportion  of  the  excluded  workmen  are  employed  by  small 
masters,  themselves  often  little  removed  from  the  status  of 
wage-earners,  or  by  migratory  contractors  of  one  kind  or 
another,  only  just  living  from  hand  to  mouth.  Insurance  in 
such  cases  would  be  unusual,  if  not  even  impossible.  Any 
serious  accident  in  their  little  industry  would,  on  the  one 
hand,  reduce  them  to  bankruptcy,  and,  on  the  other,  deprive 
the  sufferers  of  any  real  chance  of  extracting  compensation 
from  them.  Yet  the  two-thirds  of  the  wage-earners  thus 
employed  cannot  permanently  be  denied  the  compensation 
for  all  accidents  now  granted  to  the  other  third.  If  it  is 
socially  expedient  to  compensate  the  workers  in  the  great 

fishermen  ;  carmen  and  drovers  and  others  dealing  with  horses  and  cattle ;  and 
such  riverside  occupations  as  boatmen  and  lightermen. 


390  Trade  Union  Function 

industries  for  all  accidents,  there  is  neither  equity  nor  good 
sense  in  withholding  a  like  compensation  from  those  who 
suffer  accidents  in  other  trades. 

In  our  opinion,  there  must  inevitably  be  a  development, 
either  towards  the  formation  of  compulsory  trade  groups, 
collectively  responsible  for  the  accidents  occurring  in  the 
establishments  of  their  members,  or  else  towards  simple  State 
compensation.  The  former  plan,  adopted  in  Germany  and 
Austria,  has  the  economic  advantage  of  making  each  in- 
dustry self-supporting,  and  thus  avoiding  the  disastrous  con- 
sequences of  the  growth  of  "  parasitic  trades,"  on  which 
we  dwell  in  the  subsequent  chapter  on  "  The  Economic 
Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism."  It  would,  moreover, 
emphasise  the  Trade  Unionist  principle  that  an  industry 
should  be  regulated  not  by  the  will  of  individual  employers, 
but  by  its  own  Common  Rules.  Organisation  among  em- 
ployers, and  therefore  Collective  Bargaining,  would  be  greatly 
promoted,  with  the  result  that  a  great  impulse  would  prob- 
ably be  given  to  Trade  Unionism  itself.  But  the  necessary 
regimentation  of  employers  and  their  control  by  rigid  rules 
would  be  extremely  distasteful  to  English  capitalists,  whilst 
there  would  be  real  difficulty  in  adapting  any  such  organisa- 
tion to  the  remarkable  variety,  complexity,  and  mobility  of 
English  industry.  Simple  State  compensation  avoids  all 
these  difficulties,  and  requires  no  more  regimentation  or  regis- 
tration than  is  already  submitted  to  by  every  mine  or  factory 
owner.  If  it  is  desired,  as  the  Marquis  of  Salisbury  declared  in 
the  House  of  Lords  in  support  of  Mr.  Chamberlain's  bill,  to 
create  a  great  life-saving  machine,  State  compensation  affords 
the  most  effective  means  to  this  end.  The  fact  that  the  Treasury 
paid  for  every  casualty  would  change  the  official  bias  about 
dangerous  trades,  and  we  should  promptly  have  the  Govern- 
ment setting  its  scientific  advisers  and  factory  inspectors  to 
work  to  devise  new  means  of  preventing  accidents,  to  be 
enforced  by  the  Factories,  Mines,  Railways,  and  Merchant 
Shipping  Acts.  The  public  inquests  into  all  serious  cases 
would  themselves  do  much  to  make  the  capitalists  take 


Sanitation  and  Safety  39 1 

every  possible  precaution,  and  the  Factory  Inspector's 
criminal  prosecution  of  careless  employers,  which  could  not 
be  "  insured  against "  or  avoided  by  bankruptcy,  would  do 
the  rest.  Nor  would  the  employers  object.  Now  that  Mr. 
Chamberlain  has,  in  most  of  our  staple  trades,  made  them 
individually  liable  for  all  accidents,  a  Government  which 
proposed,  as  the  only  practicable  way  of  extending  compen- 
sation to  the  other  industries,  to  place  the  liability  directly  on 
the  State,  and  to  spread  its  cost  impartially  over  the  whole 
body  of  income-tax  payers  (requiring,  perhaps,  an  additional 
threepence  in  the  pound),  might  count  on  the  powerful  sup- 
port of  the  great  capitalists  in  the  coal,  iron,  and  railway 
industries,  who  would  find  themselves  relieved  of  the  special 
and  exceptional  burden  now  cast  upon  them. 


CHAPTER    VIII 

NEW    PROCESSES    AND    MACHINERY 

A  GENERATION  ago  it  was  assumed,  as  a  matter  of  course, 
by  almost  every  educated  person,  that  it  was  a  cardinal  tenet 
of  Trade  Unionism  to  oppose  machinery  and  the  introduc- 
tion of  improved  processes  of  manufacture.  "  Trade  Unions," 
said  a  well-known  critic  of  the  workmen  in  1860,  "have 
ever  naturally  opposed  the  introduction  of  machinery,  such 
introduction  tending  apparently  to  reduce  the  amount  of 
manual  labor  needed,  and  thus  pressing  on  the  majority. 
No  Trade  Union  ever  encouraged  invention."1  In  support 
of  this  opinion  might  have  been  quoted,  for  instance,  the 
editor  of  the  Potters'  Examiner,  an  influential  leader  of  the 
Potters'  Trade  Unions,  who  in  I  844  could  still  confidently 
appeal  to  experience  in  ascribing  all  the  evils  of  the  factory 
operatives  to  this  one  cause.  "  Machinery,"  he  wrote,  "  has 
done  the  work.  Machinery  has  left  them  in  rags  and  with- 
out any  wages  at  all.  Machinery  has  crowded  them  in 
cellars,  has  immured  them  in  prisons  worse  than  Parisian 
bastilles,  has  forced  them  from  their  country  to  seek  in  other 
lands  the  bread  denied  to  them  here.  I  look  upon  all 
improvements  which  tend  to  lessen  the  demand  for  human 
labor  as  the  deadliest  curse  that  could  possibly  fall  on  the 
heads  of  our  working  classes,  and  I  hold  it  to  be  the  duty  of 

1  "Trades  Unions  and  their  Tendencies,"  by  Edmund  Potter,  F.R.S.,  in  the 
Transactions  of  the  National  Association  for  the  Promotion  of  Social  Science 
(London,  1860),  p.  761. 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  393 

every  working  potter — the  highest  duty — to  obstruct  by  all 
legal  means  the  introduction  of  the  scourge  into  any  branch 
of  his  trade." 

Nowadays  we  hear  no  such  complaints.  When  in  1892 
Professor  Marshall  published  a  careful  criticism  of  Trade 
Union  policy  and  its  results,  he  deliberately  refrained  from 
taking  into  account  or  even  mentioning,  the  traditional 
hostility  of  Trade  Unions  to  inventions  or  machinery.1  And 
when  in  1894,  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor  reported 
the  result  of  its  three  years'  elaborate  and  costly  inquiry  into 
the  claims  and  proceedings  of  the  workmen's  organisations, 
it  found  no  reason  to  repair  this  significant  omission.  The 
Commissioners  heard  the  complaints  of  employers  in  every 
trade,  and  certainly  exhibited  no  desire  to  gloss  over  the  faults 
of  the  workmen.  But  if  we  may  trust  the  summary  of  evi- 
dence embodied  in  the  lengthy  Majority  Report,  resistance  to 
machinery  no  longer  forms  part  of  the  procedure  of  British 
Trade  Unionism.  Although  the  Commissioners  analysed  the 
"  rules  and  regulations "  of  hundreds  of  separate  Trade 
Unions,  in  none  of  them  did  it  discover  any  trace  of  antag- 
onism to  invention  or  improvement.2 

The  fact  is  that  Trade  Unionism  on  this  subject  has 
changed  its  attitude.  It  is  quite  true  that  during  the  first 
half  of  the  century  the  Trade  Unionist  view  was  that  so 
forcibly  expressed  in  the  Potters'  Examiner.  But  in  1859 
it  was  noticed  by  a  contemporary  scientific  observer  that 
neither  the  Trade  Unions  in  general,  nor  even  those  in  the 
same  industry,  showed  any  real  sympathy  with  the 
Northamptonshire  bootmakers'  strike  against  the  sewing- 
machine,  "  deeming  it  neither  desirable  nor  practical  to  resist 
the  extension  of  mechanical  improvements,  although  very 
sensible  of  the  inconvenience  and  suffering  that  are  sometimes 
caused  by  a  rapid  change  in  the  nature  and  extent  of  the 

1  Elements  of  the  Economics  of  Industry  (London,  1892),  Book  VI.  ch.  xiii. 
"  Trade  Unions." 

2  See,    in   particular,   the  voluminous   analysis    of   Rules  of  Associations   of 
Employers  and  of  Employed,  C.  6795,  PP-  xu-  5X3'      1892. 


394  Trade  Union  Function 

employment  afforded  in  any  particular  trade."1  In  1862  the 
Liverpool  Coopers,  who  had  formally  boycotted  machinery  in 
1853,  resolved  "  that  we  permit  any  member  of  this  society 
to  go  to  work  at  the  steam  cooperage."  2  During  this  decade 
the  Monthly  Circular  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Ironmoulders 
contains  numerous  earnest  exhortations  by  the  Executive 
Committee  to  the  members  not  to  resist  "  the  iron  man,"  the 
new  machine  for  iron  moulding.  "  It  may  go  against  the 
grain,"  they  say  in  December  1864,  "  for  us  to  fraternise  with 
what  we  consider  innovations,  but  depend  upon  it,  it  will 
be  our  best  policy  to  lay  hold  of  these  improvements  and 
make  them  subservient  to  our  best  interests."3  The  United 
Society  of  Brushmakers,  which  had  in  1863  and  1867  sup- 
ported its  members  in  refusing  to  bore  work  by  steam 
machinery,  and  had  formally  declared  that  they  must  "  on  no 
account  set  work  bored  by  steam  by  strangers,"  *  revised  its 
rules  in  1 868,  and  decided  "  that  should  any  of  our  employers 
wish  to  introduce  steam  power  for  boring,  no  opposition  shall 
be  offered  by  any  of  our  divisions,  but  each  division  shall  have 
the  discretionary  power  of  deciding  the  advantage  derived 
from  its  use." 5  These  conversions  gain  in  emphasis  and 
definiteness  from  decade  to  decade,  until,  at  the  present  day, 
no  declaration  against  innovations  or  improvements  would 
receive  support  from  the  Trade  Union  Congress  or  any 

1  "  Account  of  the  Strike  of  the  Northamptonshire  Boot  and  Shoe-makers  in 
1857,  1858,  1859,"  by  John  Ball,  F.R.S.,  Irish  Poor  Law  Commissioner  and 
(1855-1858)  Under-Secretary  of  State  for  the  Colonies;    better  known  as  the 
founder  of  the  Alpine  Club.      Printed  in  the  Report  of  Social  Science  Association 
on  Trade  Societies  and  Strikes,  1860,  p.  6.      The  same  volume  refers  (p.  149)  to 
the  fact  that  the  organ  of  the  Chainmakers'  union  "  did  not  hesitate  to  condemn 
as  foolish  the  strike  of  the  shoemakers  in  the  Midland  Counties  against  the  intro- 
duction of  machinery." 

2  MS.  Minutes  of  the  Liverpool  Coopers'  Friendly  Society,  July   1853  and 
September  1862. 

3  Friendly  Society  of  Ironmoulders,  Monthly  Circular,  December  1864. 

4  Annual  Report  of  the  United  Society  of  Brushmakers  for   1863.     See  also 
Report  for  1867. 

6  Rules  of  the  United  Society  of  Brushmakers,  edition  of  1869.  Such  few 
disputes  as  have  since  occurred  in  this  society  have  arisen  (like  that  at  Norwich 
in  1892)  over  the  exact  amount  of  the  piecework  rate  to  be  paid  on  machine 
work. 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  395 

similar  gathering.1  Among  all  the  thousand-and-one  rules 
of  existing  Trade  Unions  we  have  discovered  only  a  single 
survival  of  the  old  irreconcilable  prohibition,  and  that  in 
a  tiny  local  industry,  which  is  rapidly  fading  away.  The 
Operative  Pearl  Button  and  Stud  Workers'  Protection 
Society,  established  at  Birmingham  in  1843,  and  numbering 
about  500  members,  enjoys  the  distinction  of  being,  so  far  as 
we  are  aware,  the  only  British  Trade  Union  which  still  pro- 
hibits working  by  machinery.  Its  latest  "  Rules  and  Regula- 
tions "  declare  "  that  the  system  of  centering  by  the  engine 
be  annihilated  in  toto,  and  any  member  countenancing  the 
system  direct  or  indirect  shall  be  subject  to  a  fine  of  two 
pounds.  Any  member  of  the  society  working  at  the  trade 
by  means  of  mill-power  either  direct  or  indirect,  shall  be 
subject  to  a  fine  of  five  pounds."  2 

But  every  newspaper  reader  knows  that  the  introduction 
of  machinery  still  causes  disputes  and  strikes  ;  and  no  doubt 
many  excellent  citizens  still  pass  by  the  reports  of  such  dis- 
putes as  records  of  the  old  vain  struggle  of  the  handworker 
against  the  advance  of  industrial  civilisation.  An  examina- 
tion of  the  reports  would,  however,  show  that  the  dispute 
now  arises,  not  on  the  question  whether  machinery  should 
be  introduced,  but  about  the  conditions  of  its  introduction. 
The  change  has  even  gone  so  far  that  there  are  now,  as  we 
shall  show,  instances  of  trouble  being  caused  by  Trade  Unions 

1  The  latest  case  in  which  a  union  has  ordered  a  strike  simply  against  the 
introduction  of  machinery  into  a  hand  industry  is,  so  far  as  we  know,  that  of  the 
Liverpool  Packing  Case  Makers'  Society  in   1886.     The  strike  failed,  and  the 
men  have  since  worked  amicably  with  the  machine,  and  have  now  become  com- 
pletely reconciled   to  it  on   finding,  as  their  secretary  informed   us,  that  it  had 
largely  increased  the  trade. 

2  Rules  and  Regulations  to  be  observed  by  the  members  of  the  Pearl  Btitton  and 
Stud  Worker?  Protection  Society,  held  at  the  Baptist  Chapel,  Guildford  Street, 
Birmingham  (Birmingham,  1887),  Rule  26,  p.  14. 

We  believe  that  two  or  three  of  the  old-fashioned  trade  clubs  in  branches  of 
the  Sheffield  Cutlery  trades,  such,  for  instance,  as  the  File  Forgers  and  the  Table- 
blade  Forgers,  still  refuse  to  recognise  the  new  machines  which  are  largely  at 
work  in  their  trades,  and  which  are  therefore  operated  by  a  new  class  of  workmen. 
On  the  other  hand,  other  local  unions  such  as  the  File  cutters,  Sawsmiths,  and 
the  Pen  and  Pocket  Blade  Forgers,  have  made  no  objection  to  the  machines,  and 
liave  encouraged  their  members  to  take  to  them. 


396  Trade  Union  Function 

putting  pressure  on  old-fashioned  employers  to  compel  them 
to  adopt  the  newest  inventions.  The  typical  dispute  to-day 
is  a  dispute  as  to  terms.  The  adoption  of  a  new  machine, 
or  the  introduction  of  a  new  process,  in  superseding  an  old 
method  of  production,  usually  upsets  the  rates  of  wages  based 
on  the  older  method,  and  renders  necessary  a  fresh  scale  of 
payment.  If  wages  are  reckoned  by  the  piece,  the  employers 
will  seek  to  reduce  the  rate  per  piece  ;  if  by  time,  the  workers 
will  claim  a  rise  for  the  increased  intensity  and  strain  of  the 
newer  and  swifter  process.  In  either  case  the  readjustment 
will  involve  more  or  less  higgling,  in  which  the  points  at  issue 
are  seldom  confined  merely  to  the  amount  of  remuneration. 
The  degree  of  difficulty  in  any  such  readjustment  will 
depend  on  the  good  sense  of  the  parties  to  the  negotiations  ; 
and  in  this  as  in  other  matters  good  sense  has  to  be  acquired 
by  experience.  Some  industries,  cotton -spinning  for  ex- 
ample, have  had  a  century  of  experience  of  readjustments 
of  this  kind,  which  have  accordingly  become  a  matter  of 
routine.  But  in  trades  in  which  the  use  of  machinery, 
and  even  the  factory  system  itself,  are  still  comparatively 
new  developments,  the  readjustments  are  seldom  arrived  at 
without  a  struggle. 

As  a  typical  instance  of  a  trade  in  this  stage,  take  the 
modern  factory  industry  of  boot  and  shoe  manufacture,  which 
is  notorious  for  incessant  disputes  about  the  introduction  of 
machinery.  In  this  trade  the  compact  little  union  of  handi- 
craftsmen, working  for  rich  customers,  has  long  since  been 
outstripped  by  its  offshoot,  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and 
Shoe  Operatives,  formed  exclusively  of  factory  workers,  and 
numbering,  at  the  end  of  1896,  37,000  members.  We  have 
here  an  industry  which  is  being  incessantly  revolutionised 
by  an  almost  perpetual  stream  of  new  inventions  and  new 
applications  of  the  old  machines.  The  workmen  are  noted 
for  their  turbulence,  want  of  discipline,  and  lack  of  education. 
The  employers,  themselves  new  capitalists  without  traditions, 
exposed  to  keen  rivalry  from  foreign  competitors,  are  eager 
to  take  the  utmost  advantage  of  every  chance.  The  disputes 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  397 

are  endless,  and  the  prolonged  conference  proceedings,  the 
elaborate  arguments  before  the  arbitrators,  and  the  complicated 
agreements  with  the  employers  are  all  printed  in  full,  afford- 
ing a  complete  picture  of  the  attitudes  taken  up  by  the 
masters  and  the  men. 

The  employers'  indictment   of  the   operatives  has  been 

graphically  summed  up  by  their  principal  literary  spokesman. 

(<  It  is  true,"  says  the  editor  of  the  employers'  journal,  "  that 

objection  does  not  take  the  form  of  rattening  or  direct  refusal 

to  work  with  the  machines  ;  experience  has  taught  the  union 

a  more  efficacious  way  of  marshalling  the  forces  of  opposition. 

To  say  openly  that  labor-saving  appliances  were  objected  to 

would  be  to  estrange   that  public  sympathy  without  which 

Trade  Unionism  finds  itself  unable  to  live.    So  other  methods 

are  adopted.      The  work  done  by  the  machines  is  belittled  ; 

it  is  urged  that  no  saving  of  labor  is  effected  by  their  use  ; 

the  men  working  the  machines  exercise  all  their  ingenuity 

in   making    machine    work    as    expensive    as    hand    labor. 

There    exists    among    workmen    what    amounts   to   a   tacit 

understanding  that  only  so  much  work  shall   be  done  within 

a  certain  time,  and,  no  matter  what  machines  are  introduced, 

the  men  conspire  to  prevent  any  saving  being  effected   by 

their  aid.      It  is  of  no  use  to  mince  words.      The  unions  are 

engaged  in   a  gigantic  conspiracy  to  hinder  and   retard  the 

development    of    labor-saving   appliances    in    this    country. 

The    action    of   their    members    in    failing   to   exercise   due 

diligence  in  working  new  machines  is  equivalent  to  absolute 

dishonesty.      It  is,  indeed,  positively  painful  to  any  one  who 

has  been  accustomed  to  see,  for  example,  finishing  machinery 

running  in  American   factories,  to  watch  English  operatives 

using  the  same  machines.      In   America  the  men  work,  they 

run  the  machines  to  their  utmost  capacity,  and  vie  with  each 

other  in  their  endeavor  to   get  through  as    much   work   as 

possible.      But  in  an  English  factory  they  seem  to  loaf  away 

their  time  in  a  manner  which  is  perfectly  exasperating.      If 

they  run  a  machine  for  five  minutes  at  full  speed,  they  seem 

to  think  it  necessary  to  stop  it  and  see  that  no  breakage  has 


398  Trade  Union  Function 

occurred.  Then  they  walk  about  the  shop,  and  borrow  an 
oil-can  or  a  spanner,  wherewith  to  do  some  totally  unnecessary 
thing.  This  occupies  anywhere  from  five  minutes  to  an  hour, 
and  then  the  machine  is  run  on  again  for  a  few  minutes  ; 
and  if  the  operator  is  questioned,  he  says,  '  machines  are  no 
good  ;  I  could  do  the  work  quicker  and  better  by  hand.' 
And  so  he  could,  for  he  takes  care  not  to  allow  a  machine  to 
beat  a  shopmate  working  by  hand  on  the  same  job,  and,  in 
short,  does  all  he  can  to  induce  manufacturers  to  abandon 
mechanical  devices  and  go  back  to  hand  labor.  The  spirit 
of  comradeship  is  carried  to  a  ridiculous  extent,  and  no  man 
dare  do  the  best  he  can,  lest  his  fellow-workmen  should  be, 
as  he  foolishly  thinks,  injured.  ...  It  seems  to  be  a  settled 
policy  with  the  men,  not  to  try  to  earn  as  much  money  as 
possible  per  week,  but  as  much  as  possible  per  job,  in  other 
words,  to  keep  the  cost  of  production  as  high  as  possible." l 

Assuming  all  this  to  be  true  in  fact — and,  so  far,  at  any 
rate  as  times  of  strained  relations  are  concerned,  there  is  no 
reason  to  question  its  accuracy — let  us  supplement  it  by  two 
other  facts  which  would  hardly  have  been  inferred  from  it. 
First,  that  in  the  American  boot  factories  which  work  at  such 
high  pressure,  the  high  pressure  is  invariably  paid  for  by 
piecework  rates.  Second,  that  in  England  it  is  the  workmen 
who  demand  that,  in  conjunction  with  the  new  machines  they 
should  be  allowed  to  work  by  the  piece,  as  they  have  hither- 
to been  accustomed,  and  that  it  is  the  employers  who  have 
resolutely  insisted  on  taking  the  opportunity  of  changing  to 
fixed  day  wages.2  Here  lies  the  clue  to  the  whole  difficulty. 
We  have  already  explained,  in  connection  with  the  Cotton- 
spinners,  how  piecework  is  the  only  possible  protection  of  the 
Standard  Rate  for  men  who  are  working  machines  of  which 

1  The  Shoe  and  Leather  Record,  ipth  February  1892. 

2  Thus  one  of  the  so-called  "  Seven  Commandments  " — the  ultimatum  of  the 
employers  against  which  the  great  strike  of  1895  took  place — was  the  following 
"That  the  present  is  not  an  opportune  time  for  the  introduction  of  piecework  in 
connection  with  lasting  and  finishing  machinery  "(Labour  Gazette^  November  1894). 
The  lasters  and  finishers  have  been  accustomed  to  work  by  the  piece  ever  since 
the  beginning  of  the  factory  boot  industry. 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  399 

the  rate  of  speed  is  always  being  increased.  On  such  machines 
payment  by  the  hour,  day,  or  week  involves  the  exacting 
from  the  operative  an  ever-increasing  task  of  work  in  return 
for  the  old  wages.  In  the  case  of  the  boot  operatives  the 
question  is  complicated  by  the  fact  that  the  new  machines 
have  introduced  a  new  organisation  of  the  factory,  the  work- 
man steadily  becoming  less  and  less  of  an  individual  producer, 
working  at  his  own  speed,  and  more  and  more  a  member  of 
a  "  team,"  or  set  of  operatives  each  performing  a  small  part 
of  the  process,  and  thus  obliged  to  keep  up  with  each  other. 
This  enforced  "  speeding  up  "  would  be  all  very  well  if  the 
old  plan  of  paying  by  the  piece  were  continued.  But  when 
the  "  more  efficient  organisation  of  labor  "  is  coupled  with 
the  introduction  of  a  fixed  day  wage,  the  workmen  see  in  it 
an  attempt  to  lower  the  Standard  Rate  of  remuneration  for 
effort,  by  getting  more  labor  in  return  for  the  old  payment. 

This  position  the  employers  fail  even  to  comprehend. 
"  I  know,"  said  the  President  of  the  Employers'  Association 
in  1 894,  "  that  it  will  be  said  it  is  slavery,  pace-making,  and 
driving,  and  that  sort  of  thing.  .  .  .  But  the  manufacturers 
contend  that  that  is  not  so.  For  instance,  when  men  are  put 
to  work  in  a  team,  they  are  waited  on  hand  and  foot,  and 
they  are  never  kept  waiting  for  anything,  whereas  when  they 
have  to  '  shop '  their  (own)  work  a  waste  of  time  is  involved. 
That  time  is  saved  under  the  team  system." l  It  is  part 
of  the  brainworker's  usual  ignorance  of  the  conditions  of 
manual  labor  that  the  leaders  of  the  employers  could  naively 
imagine  that,  to  be  "  never  kept  waiting  for  anything,"  is  an 
advantage  to  the  man  paid  a  fixed  daily  wage.  To  the 
workman  it  means  being  kept  incessantly  toiling  at  the  very 
top  of  his  speed  for  the  whole  nine  hours  of  the  factory  day. 
When  this  high  pressure  is  demanded  for  the  old  earnings, 
it  amounts  to  a  clear  attempt  to  lower  the  Standard  Rate. 
How  this  attitude  strikes  an  employer  in  the  same  trade, 

1  Report  of  the  National  Conference  between  employers  and  employed,  6th-8th 
January  1894;  reprinted  in  Monthly  Report  of  the  National  Union  Boot  and 
Shoe  Operatives,  January  1894. 


400  Trade  Union  Function 

conversant  with  American  conditions,  may  be  judged  from 
the  following  instructive  letter  written  in  reply  to  the  editorial 
first  quoted.  "  Let  us  take  a  look  into  an  English  machinery- 
equipped  factory.  What  do  we  see  there  ?  Precisely  what 
you  state,  only  much  worse.  The  workmen,  or  very  often 
boys,  who  work  on  weekly  wages,  try  how  little  work  they 
can  do  and  how  badly  they  can  do  that  little.  They  don't 
seem  to  care  a  scrap  so  long  as  they  get  the  time  over, 
and  are  glad  when  the  time  comes  to  clear  out  of  the  factory 
and  the  day's  monotony  is  over.  They  are  continually  medd- 
ling with  their  machines  and  throwing  them  out  of  order. 
Then  the  engineer  has  to  be  called  in.  The  result  is  a  loss 
of  time,  a  loss  of  work,  and  expense  also.  All  this  to  my 
mind  arises  from  a  mistaken  policy  which  English  manufacturers 
adopt  in  employing  so  much  boy  labor  and  the  weekly  wages 
system.  If  the  piecework  system  were  adopted,  and  only 
expert  men  employed  on  the  machines,  better  work  would  be 
the  result,  at  less  cost,  and  the  workman  would  earn  higher 
wages.  Is  not  that  the  secret  why  an  American  manufacturer 
can  produce  his  goods  at  a  lower  labor  cost  than  similar 
goods  can  be  produced  in  this  country,  while  at  the  same  time 
the  American  operative  is  earning  much  higher  wages  than 
his  English  brother?"1 

It  will  not  unnaturally  be  asked  why  the  English  em- 
ployers should  wantonly  raise  difficulties  by  choosing  the 
awkward  moment  of  the  introduction  of  new  machinery,  to 
compel  their  workmen  to  abandon  the  piecework  system  of 
remuneration,  which  has  for  several  generations  been  custom- 
ary, and  to  substitute  for  it  a  fixed  daily  wage.  The  manu- 
facturers explain  that,  if  piecework  rates  were  conceded  in 
connection  with  the  new  machines,  and  if  the  scale  were 
calculated  on  the  basis  of  the  workmen's  weekly  earnings  at 
the  old  process,  the  men  would  very  soon  so  increase  their 
skill  and  quickness  as  to  earn  £3  or  £4  per  week,  instead  of 
the  time  rate  of  26s.  as  at  present.  But  this,  as  every  cotton 
manufacturer  would  recognise,  is,  economically  speaking,  no 

1  Letter  in  Shoe  and  Leather  Record,  25th  February  1892. 


Nezv  Processes  and  Machinery  401 

argument  at  all.  The  able  secretary  of  the  Boot  and  Shoe 
Manufacturers'  Association  has  repeatedly  urged  upon  his 
members  that  such  a  result  would  in  no  way  raise  the  cost  of 
production  per  pair  of  boots,  and,  on  the  contrary,  would 
positively  lower  it,  by  enormously  increasing  the  output  per 
machine.  Unfortunately,  such  arguments  are  thrown  away 
on  untrained  employers,  who  even  when  they  are  contemplat- 
ing the  widest  extension  of  their  profits,  can  seldom  view 
with  equanimity  the  prospect  of  paying  their  workmen  any 
larger  amount  per  week  than  that  to  which  they  are 
accustomed.1 

The  workmen  in  the  factory  boot  trade,  equally  un- 
trained in  industrial  policy,  are  no  less  unreasonable  than 
the  employers,  and  on  a  cognate  point.  They,  too,  are  so 
scandalised  at  the  prospect  of  an  increased  reward  being 
gained  by  any  one  else,  that  they  propose  unreasonable  and 
impossible  courses  in  order  to  prevent  it.  When,  in  1894, 
the  Leicester  Branch  of  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and 
Shoe  Operatives  appointed  a  committee  to  draw  up  a 
Piecework  List  for  work  done  in  conjunction  with  the  new 
machinery,  these  workmen  na'fvely  proceeded  on  the  basis 
of  retaining  the  "  Statement "  of  piecework  rates  under  the 
old  process,  merely  deducting,  for  each  article,  a  percentage 
estimated  to  produce  a  saving  to  the  employer  exactly 
equivalent  to  the  interest  he  would  pay  on  the  cost  of  the 
new  machinery.2  Thus,  whilst  the  terms  proposed  by  the 

1  An  American  observer  notes  the  same  feeling  among  German  employers. 
"  In  Berlin  even,  I  found  this  narrow-minded  begrudging  of  a  working-man's  higher 
earnings.     In  piecework  they  reduce  the  rate  of  pay  of  the  greater  output  which 
brings  higher  earnings  than  the  general  rate.   .   .   .  The  manufacturers  returned  to 
the  day  rate.  .   .  .   because  the  masters  found  that  the  men  made  too  much  money 
under  the  piecework  system." — The  Economy  of  High  Wages,  by  J.   Schoenhof 
(New  York,  1892),  p.  400. 

The  same  struggle  took  place  between  1850  and  1860  on  the  introduction  of 
the  factory  system  and  steam  power  into  the  Coventry  ribbon  trade,  the  operatives 
demanding  piecework  rates  and  the  employers  insisting  on  introducing  fixed  day 
wages,  "  partly  because  the  piecework  system  is  a  more  troublesome  one  than  that 
of  weekly  wages,  but  chiefly  because  it  would  work  a  forfeiture  to  them  of  the 
benefit  from  the  increase  of  the  productiveness  of  their  machinery." — Social  Science 
Association,  Report  on  Trade  Societies  and  Strikes,  p.  325. 

2  Minutes  (in  MS.)  of  the  "Piecework  Committee,"  which  sat  from  April  to 

VOL.  I  2  D 


402  Trade  Union  Function 

employers  would  leave  the  workmen  no  incentive  to  use  the 
new  machines,  those  proposed  by  the  workmen  would  leave 
the  employers  no  incentive  to  introduce  them. 

The  feeling  of  the  workmen  in  this  matter  is  a  super- 
stition from  the  era  of  individual  production.  The  operative 
bootmaker  has  inherited  a  rooted  belief  that  the  legitimate 
reward  of  labor  is  the  entire  commodity  produced,  or  its 
price  in  the  market.  This  idea  was  the  economic  backbone 
of  Owenite  Socialism,  with  its  projects  of  Associations  of 
Producers  and  Labor  Exchanges.1  In  the  first  number  of 
the  Poor  Man's  Guardian,  a  widely-read  journal  of  1831,  it 
was  expressed  in  the  following  verse : — 

Wages  should  form  the  price  of  goods ; 

Yes,  wages  should  be  all, 
Then  we  who  work  to  make  the  goods, 

Should  justly  have  them  all ; 
But  if  their  price  be  made  of  rent, 

Tithes,  taxes,  profits  all, 
Then  we  who  work  to  make  the  goods, 

Shall  have,  just  none  at  all ! 2 

When  the  operative  bootmaker  proceeds  to  draft  a  piece- 
work list  for  the  new  machines,  the  rates  that  he  proposes 
really  express  in  figures  his  economic  assumption  that  "  wages 
should  be  the  price  of  goods."  This  state  of  mind  leads 
him  calmly  to  suggest,  in  effect,  that  he  should  receive  the 
entire  net  advantage  of  every  new  invention.  The  employer 
puts  in  an  equally  untenable  claim  to  enjoy  the  whole  benefit 

September  1894.  This  Committee  was  attended  by  the  prominent  workmen  of 
the  Leicester  Branch  and  the  Branch  officials.  It  is  only  fair  to  say  that  when 
it  was  seen  that  the  rates  proposed  worked  out  to  an  increase  of  wages  in  some 
cases  amounting  to  as  much  as  40  per  cent,  the  more  experienced  officials  of  the 
union  protested  against  its  proceedings  as  likely  to  bring  the  whole  policy  of  the 
union  into  disrepute. 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  ch.  iii. 

2  Place   MSS.,   27,791-240.     The  verse  is  now  reprinted  in  Dictionary  of 
Political  Economy  under   "Chartism";    and   in  the  Life  of  Francis  Place,  by 
Graham  Wallas   (London,    1897).       The  same  idea   inspired  the   proposals  of 
Lassalle,  and  most  of  the  inferences  drawn  from  Karl  Marx's   Theory  of  Value, 
whilst  it  still  lingers  in  the  declarations  and  programmes  of  German  Socialism  and 
its  derivatives.      It  is,  of  course,  inconsistent  with  present  economic  views  as  to 
the  "unearned  increment,"  arising  from  the  progress  of  invention  and  organisation 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  403 

of  the  improvement,  and  regards  the  workmen's  claim  as  an 
attack,  not  on  the  community,  but  on  himself.  But  whatever 
the  employer  may  desire,  the  community  believes  that,  in 
the  majority  of  cases,  competition  quickly  transfers  his  new 
gains  to  the  consumer  in  the  shape  of  reduced  prices.  In 
all  these  contentions,  therefore,  public  opinion  is  apt  to  be 
against  the  workmen's  claim,  even  to  the  extent  of  ignoring 
their  legitimate  demand  for  an  increase  of  earnings  com- 
mensurate with  the  greater  strain  of  the  new  process.  The 
employers  have  sometimes  known  how  to  use  this  argument 
with  great  effect  on  public  opinion.  The  London  Master 
Builders'  Committee  complained,  in  1859,  that  the  men's 
argument  in  favor  of  a  shortening  of  hours  "implied  that 
the  benefits  to  be  derived  from  machinery  are  not  the 
property  of  society,  of  its  inventors,  of  those  who  apply  it, 
but  are  to  be  appropriated  by  those  whose  labor  it  is 
alleged  it  will  displace." 1 

When  the  increase  in  production  does  not  depend  on  a 
new  machine,  but  arises  merely  from  a  further  division  of 
labor,  even  the  experienced  leaders  of  the  operatives  are 
honestly  unable  to  conceive  how  any  one  can  dispute  the 
men's  claim  to  enjoy  the  whole  increase.  In  1894  a  Bristol 
firm  was  charged  before  the  "  National  Conference "  (the 
central  joint-board)  "  with  having  introduced  a  new  system 
of  working  in  Bristol,"  the  so-called  "  team  system,"  which 
resulted  in  the  men  collectively  producing  more  boots  per 

of  population  and  capital  in  dense  masses,  upon  which  the  modern  English 
Socialist  bases  his  demand  for  collective  ownership  of  the  means  of  production, 
and  the  subordination  of  the  producer  to  the  citizen,  and  the  individual  to  the 
community.  See  Fabian  Tract,  No.  51,  Socialism,  True  and  False,  and  the 
Report  on  Fabian  Policy,  presented  by  the  Fabian  Society  to  the  International 
Socialist  Congress,  1896  (Fabian  Tract,  No.  70). 

Though  the  Owenite  assumption  here  referred  to  was  formerly  accepted  by 
large  masses  of  English  workmen,  and  though  it  still  lies  at  the  root  of  the 
desire  for  Co-operative  Associations  of  Producers,  it  cannot  be  said  to  characterise 
the  Trade  Unionism  of  the  present  day,  and  it  will  accordingly  not  be  discussed 
in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism."  The  student  should 
consult,  besides  the  works  of  Owen,  Hodgskin,  Thompson,  Lassalle,  and  Marx, 
Dr.  Anton  Menger's  Das  Recht  auf  den  vollen  Arbeitsertrag. 

1  Report  on  Trade  Societies  and  Strikes^  Social  Science  Association,  1860,  p.  62. 


404  Trade  Union  Function 

day  than  before.  As  the  charge  was  coupled  with  an 
alteration  from  piecework  to  fixed  wages,  there  would  have 
been  some  justification  for  a  complaint  that  the  Standard 
Rate  was  being  imperilled,  by  the  exaction  of  ever-increasing 
exertion  for  a  fixed  weekly  wage.  But  instead  of  taking 
this  point,  the  union  claimed  that  unless  the  day  wage  was 
so  fixed  that  the  cost  of  each  boot  to  the  employer  remained 
no  less  than  before,  the  alteration  should  be  regarded  as  a 
reduction  of  wages.1  The  men's  case  was  so  prejudiced  by 
this  argument  that  the  President  (Alderman  Sir  Thomas 
Wright)  not  only  rejected  their  claim,  but  also  went  so  far 
as  to  say  that,  provided  the  mere  weekly  earnings  were 
undiminished,  the  change  of  process  was  not  an  alteration 
of  conditions,  thus  altogether  ignoring  the  question  of  the 
increased  effort  and  strain  involved. 

The  student  of  this  remarkable  series  of  disputes  will  not 
fail  to  notice  that  the  employers  and  the  workmen  both  take 
up  positions  which  are  inconsistent  with  their  own  arguments. 
The  employers  have,  in  the  fullest  and  most  unreserved 
manner,  given  in  their  adhesion  to  the  principle  of  Collective 
Bargaining  with  regard  to  all  the  conditions  of  labor.  They 
have  emphasised  their  adhesion  to  this  principle  by  insisting 
on  the  establishment  of  a  most  elaborate  machinery  for 
carrying  on  this  Collective  Bargaining,  of  which  they  make 
constant  use.  It  is  therefore  inconsistent  of  them  to  claim 
that  any  employer  has  a  right  to  "  introduce  machinery  at 
any  time  without  notice,"  and  that  changes  in  "  the  internal 

1  The  claim  and  argument  will  be  found  in  the  Report  of  the  National  Con- 
ference of  the  Boot  and  Shoe  Trade,  August  1893.  "Supposing,"  asked  the 
President,  "the  alteration  from  piecework  to  daywork  resulted  in  the  worker 
receiving  more  money,  would  you  say  that  was  an  alteration  of  which  he  had  a 
right  to  complain  ?  "  To  this  question  the  obvious  answer  was  that  if  the  new 
process  involved  greater  exertion  or  strain  than  the  old,  an  actual  increase  of 
weekly  earnings  might  well  mean  a  lowering  of  the  Standard  Rate  (of  remuneration 
for  effort),  and  thus  involve  a  grievance  to  the  workmen.  But  instead  of  taking 
this  line  the  men's  spokesman  said,  "  I  should  say  that  if  a  particular  individual 
got  that  money  and  the  employer  got  eleven  dozen  of  work  done  at  the  price  of 
ten  dozen  provided  by  the  Statement,  that  that  involved  a  reduction  of  wages." 
The  same  confusion  of  ideas  appears  in  the  cases  of  "team  system"  discussed  at 
the  National  Conference  of  January  1894. 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  405 

economy  of  the  factory  or  the  manipulation  of  the  workmen  " 
are  matters  for  the  autocratic  decision  of  each  individual 
factory  owner.  It  is  no  doubt,  a  question  for  each  employer 
to  determine  whether  or  not  he  will  introduce  a  particular 
machine,  just  as  it  is  for  him  alone  to  decide  whether  or  not 
he  will  engage  twenty  additional  workmen.  But  the  regula- 
tions and  conditions  under  which  the  men  will  be  engaged, 
or  will  change  their  habits  of  work,  are  obviously  matters 
which,  on  the  assumption  of  Collective  Bargaining,  cannot  be 
settled  by  the  will  of  one  party  to  the  wage  contract,  or  even 
by  the  agreement  of  particular  employers  and  particular 
workmen,  but  must  be  arranged  as  a  Common  Rule  by 
negotiation  between  the  authorised  representatives  of  both 
sides.  The  employers,  moreover,  have  repeatedly  adopted  in 
their  negotiations  the  principle  of  the  Standard  Rate,  that 
is,  the  uniform  maintenance  throughout  the  trade  of  identical 
payment  for  identical  effort.  It  is  therefore  inconsistent  of 
them  to  insist  on  fixed  time  wages,  on  a  change  of  process 
which  must  inevitably  result  in  progressively  increasing  the 
intensity  of  effort  imposed  on  the  workmen.  Unless  there 
is  some  arrangement  by  which  the  operatives  are  ensured 
progressively  increasing  earnings,  proportionate  to  this  pro- 
gressively increasing  intensity,  the  employers  are  under- 
mining the  Standard  Rate,  that  is,  insidiously  diminishing 
the  rate  of  payment  for  a  given  amount  of  effort  The 
operatives,  on  the  other  hand,  whilst  recognising  that  their 
very  existence  as  factory  bootmakers  depends  on  the  super- 
session of  the  individual  hand  bootmaker,  are  always  re- 
senting the  further  division  of  labor  and  the  increased  use 
of  machinery.  And  though  they  take  their  stand  on  the 
fundamental  principle  of  maintaining  the  Standard  Rate, 
and  therefore  of  insisting  on  a  Piecework  Statement,  they 
yet  cannot  bring  themselves  in  the  new  processes  to  propose 
rates  which  would  work  out,  even  at  the  start,  to  earnings 
equivalent  only  to  their  present  wages.  If  the  men  frankly 
asked  for  an  increase  in  their  Standard  Rate  of  so  much 
per  cent,  to  be  worked  out  in  detail  by  a  revision  of  the 


406  Trade  Union  Function 

"  Statement,"  the  claim  would  be  discussed  on  its  own 
merits,  as  an  incident  in  the  perennial  higgling  between 
employers  and  employed.  It  may  well  be  that  the  moment 
when  profits  are  being  largely  increased  by  a  change  of 
process,  is  a  specially  opportune  occasion  for  a  rise  of  wage. 
But,  when  the  demand  for  an  advance  is  disguised  in  an 
assumption  that  any  departure  from  the  old  "  Statement "  is 
to  be  resisted  as  a  positive  reduction,  the  employers  get  into 
a  state  of  inarticulate  rage  at  what  seems  to  them  the 
intellectual  dishonesty  of  the  men's  proceedings.  If  the 
operatives  desire  to  maintain  the  modern  Trade  Union 
principle  of  the  Standard  Rate,  they  must  abandon,  once 
for  all,  the  diametrically  opposite  assumption  that  "  wages 
should  be  the  price  of  goods,"  and  at  once  set  about  the 
compilation  of  a  new  piecework  list  applicable  to  the  great 
variety  of  machines  and  diversity  of  conditions  in  the  various 
factories.  Such  a  list  would,  no  doubt,  cost  trouble,  especially 
in  view  of  the  survival  of  many  small  manufacturers,  each 
using  only  one  or  more  of  the  new  machines.  But  similar 
difficulties  were  met  and  overcome  twenty  years  ago  when 
the  trade  became  a  factory  industry,  and  American  experience 
shows  that  they  are  not  insuperable  to-day.1 

The  gradual  introduction  of  composing  and  distributing 
machines  into  the  English  printing  trade  affords  an  instance 
of  somewhat  similar  difficulties  in  another  industry.  These 
machines  began  to  be  used  about  1876,  but,  owing  to  the 
imperfections  of  the  earlier  inventions,  it  was  not  until  the 

1  The  experience  of  the  English  Co-operative  Wholesale  Society,  whose 
colossal  boot  factory  remained  unaffected  by  the  general  stoppage  of  1895,  is 
interesting  in  showing  how  an  exceptionally  able  manager,  himself  once  an 
operative,  has  (in  anticipation  of  the  agreement  of  a  piecework  list  for  the  new 
processes)  partially  solved  the  problem,  by  making  the  weekly  wages  roughly 
proportionate  to  the  increasing  output.  On  a  certain  "  lasting  machine  "  the  out- 
put varies  from  666  pairs  per  week  to  as  much  as  1270,  according  to  the  skill 
and  zeal  of  the  operator.  Mr.  Butcher  has  known  how  to  encourage  zeal  and 
skill,  by  refusing  to  adhere  to  the  uniform  rate  per  week  given  by  many  of  the 
employers  to  all  their  workmen  in  each  process  ;  paying  as  much  as  405.  to  the 
principal  operator,  and  (instead  of  taking  on  boys)  giving  355.  a  week  even  to 
his  "followers."  He  declares  his  intention,  on  the  output  rising  to  1500  pairs  a 
week,  to  increase  the  wages  to  £2  :  los. 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  407 

last  decade  of  the  century  that  their  competition  with  the 
old  hand  compositor  came  to  be  seriously  felt.  The  advent 
of  the  machine  has  throughout  been  most  distasteful  to  the 
men.  But  the  Compositors'  Trade  Unions  have  from  the 
first  disclaimed  any  desire  to  prevent  its  introduction,  or  to 
forbid  the  members  to  work  it.  Their  policy  has  been  to 
secure  the  new  employment  to  their  own  members  on  terms 
which  protected  their  Standard  Rate.  No  pretension  on 
their  part  to  receive  the  whole  advantage  of  the  Linotype 
machine  is  on  record,  but  it  is  asserted  that  they  have 
claimed  a  share  of  it.  The  Chairman  of  the  Linotype 
Company,  speaking  to  his  shareholders  in  1893,  declared 
that  "  Nearly  all  the  offices  which  have  taken  the  Linotype 
are  union  offices — in  some  cases  working  by  day,  and  in 
other  cases  working  by  piece.  Surely  that  is  sufficient 
proof  that  the  labor  difficulty  is  not  a  very  serious  one.  The 
union  [men]  have,  in  my  opinion,  acted  very  fairly  towards 
us.  All  they  have  said  is  this  :  *  Our  men  think  you  have 
an  invention  which  is  a  great  advantage  to  the  trade — saves 
a  great  deal  of  money  and  labor — and  the  men  should  have 
their  fair  share  of  the  advantages.'  Let  the  masters  pay 
them  fairly,  and  then  I  believe  there  will  be  no  difficulty 
whatever  in  introducing  this  machine."1  In  1894,  the 
London  Society  of  Compositors  was  able  to  come  to  a 
satisfactory  agreement  with  the  newspaper  proprietors,  who 
have  up  to  the  present  been  the  chief  users  of  the  machine, 
and  it  is  now  at  work  in  the  London  newspaper  offices  under 
conditions  formally  accepted  by  both  parties.2 

1  Speech  of  the  Chairman  of  the  Linotype  Company,  at  the  Ordinary  General 
Meeting  of  Shareholders,  Cannon  Street  Hotel,  London,  nth  May  1893. 

2  New  and  amended  rules  agreed  to  at  a  Conference  between  the  Representa- 
tives of  the  London  Daily  Newspaper  Proprietors,  and  of  the  London  Society  of 
Compositors,  held  at  Anderton's  Hotel  on  7th  June  1894. 

Composing  machines. 

1.  All  skilled  operators — i.e.  compositors,  justifiers,  and  distributors,  as  dis- 
tinct from  attendants  or  laborers — shall  be  members  of  the  London  Society  of 
Compositors,   preference  being  given   to  members  of  the  Companionship    into 
which  the  machines  are  introduced.      Distribution  to  be  paid  at  a  minimum  rate 
of  385.  per  week  of  48  hours,  day-work. 

2.  A  Probationary  Period  of  three  months  shall  be  allowed,  the  operator  to 


408  Trade  Union  Function 

Now  let  us  turn  from  the  trades  in  which  the  introduc- 
tion of  new  machinery  is  recent  enough  to  be  a  source  of 
continual  friction  to  those  in  which  this  has  long  ceased  to 
be  the  case.  In  the  great  industries  of  cotton-spinning  and 
cotton-weaving  every  part  of  the  machinery  employed  has, 
during  the  last  hundred  years,  been  enormously  improved. 
In  the  early  stages  of  this  mechanical  progress  each  step 
was  the  subject  of  furious  strife  between  masters  and  men, 
on  much  the  same  lines  as  the  battles  now  being  fought  in 
the  boot  and  shoe  industry.  For  the  last  thirty  years,  how- 
ever, the  unions  have  genuinely  abandoned  all  idea  of  oppos- 
ing improvements,  or  of  exacting  the  whole  advantage  of 
their  introduction.  The  conditions  under  which  any  improve- 
ments in  machinery  shall  be  introduced  have,  by  common 
consent,  long  since  been  taken  out  of  the  hands  of  the 
individual  employer,  or  the  particular  group  of  operatives. 
Any  change  whatsoever  in  "the  internal  economy  of  the 
factory,  or  the  manipulation  of  the  workmen  by  the 
employer" — which,  to  the  new  class  of  boot  manufacturers, 
seems  a  matter  for  their  own  autocratic  decision — is,  in  the 
cotton  industry,  referred  as  a  matter  of  course  for  prior 
deliberation  and  agreement  between  the  expert  salaried 
officials  of  the  Trade  Union  and  the  Employers'  Association. 
As  the  basis  of  negotiation,  the  principle  of  maintaining  in- 
tact the  Standard  Rate  of  payment  for  a  given  quantity  of 
effort  is  unreservedly  accepted  by  both  sides.  The  employers 

receive  his  average  weekly  earnings  for  the  previous  three  months.      During  this 
period  he  shall  not  undertake  piecework. 

3.  In  all  offices  when  composing  machines  are  introduced,  the  operators  and 
case  hands  shall  commence  composition  simultaneously.   .   .   .   Compositors  and 
operators  in  such  offices  to  be  guaranteed  two  galleys  per  day  of  seven  working 
hours  on  Morning  papers,  and  on  Evening  papers  twelve  galleys  per  week  of  42 
hours. 

4.  The  scale  of  prices  for  machine  work  shall  be,  Linotype,  3^d.   per  one 
thousand  ens  for  day-work  in  Evening  paper  offices,  3|d.  per  thousand  ens  for 
work  done  in  Morning  paper  offices,  £d.  per  one  thousand  extra  on  all  types  above 
brevier ;  Hattersley,  4d.  per  one  thousand  ens  for  Evening  paper  work,  and  4^d. 
per  one  thousand  ens  for  Morning  paper  work. 

This  agreement  was,  in  1896,  superseded  by  a  more  elaborate  one,  framed 
on  similar  lines. — See  Labour  Gazette,  August  1896. 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  409 

recognise  that  any  increased  speed  or  complexity  of  the 
process  means  increased  intensity  of  effort  to  the  operative, 
which  must  therefore  be  remunerated  by  progressively  in- 
creasing earnings.  They  would  never  dream  of  suggesting 
the  substitution  of  fixed  time  rates  of  wages,  and  they  agree, 
without  demur,  to  a  Piecework  List  which,  definitely  fixed 
in  advance,  completely  secures  to  the  workmen  these  pro- 
gressive earnings.  On  the  other  hand,  the  operatives  have 
unreservedly  abandoned  any  idea  that  "wages  should  be 
the  price  of  goods."  We  can  imagine  the  amusement  with 
which  such  experienced  Trade  Union  officials  as  Mr.  Mawds- 
ley  or  Mr.  Wilkinson  would  listen  to  the  suggestion  that 
any  lowering  of  the  cost  per  yard  to  the  employer  must 
necessarily  be  a  reduction  of  wages  to  the  operative.  They 
would  reply  that,  so  long  as  the  cotton  operative  was  assured 
of  his  Standard  Rate,  he  had  no  concern  with  the  cost  of 
production  at  all,  except  that  any  reduction  resulting  from 
wise  administration  or  improvement  of  process  was  posi- 
tively advantageous  to  the  workmen,  by  securing  for  their 
product  an  ever-extending  market.  The  Trade  Unions  of 
cotton  operatives  actually  meet  the  innovating  employers 
half-way,  by  agreeing  to  a  piecework  rate  which  decreases 
with  every  rise  in  the  productivity  of  machinery.  The 
employer  therefore  knows  that  every  improvement  that  he 
can  introduce  will  bring  him  a  real,  though  not  an  unlimited, 
saving  in  his  cost  of  production.  The  operatives,  on  the 
other  hand,  have  the  assurance  that  the  graduated  piecework 
rates,  already  settled  by  mutual  agreement,  after  careful 
consideration  by  their  expert  officials,  will  not  only  protect 
their  present  weekly  earnings,  but  will  also  immediately 
remunerate  them  for  any  increased  effort  involved.  They 
have  learnt,  moreover,  by  experience,  that  any  consciousness 
of  the  increased  effort  will  soon  disappear  as  the  closer 
attention  and  quicker  movement  become  habitual.  It  is 
true  that  by  accepting  a  lower  piecework  rate  they  give  up 
any  claim  to  monopolise  for  themselves  the  "  unearned 
increment "  of  the  new  invention.  On  the  other  hand,  they 


4io  Trade  Union  Function 

are  secured  by  the  employers'  concession  of  a  predetermined 
Piecework  List,  in  all  the  "  rent "  of  the  new  dexterity  which 
practice  at  the  new  process  inevitably  produces.  Thus,  the 
steadily  rising  speed  of  working,  which  to  the  boot  opera- 
tive, compelled  by  his  employer  to  labor  at  a  fixed  time 
wage,  is  "  pace-making  and  slavery,"  means  to  the  cotton- 
spinner  a  welcome  addition  to  his  weekly  earnings,  and  a 
permanent  rise  in  his  Standard  of  Life. 

The  United  Society  of  Boilermakers  and  Iron-ship- 
builders base  their  agreements  with  their  employers  on 
similar  principles.  Thus  the  internal  economy  of  the  vast 
shipbuilding  industry  of  the  North-East  coast  of  England 
is  governed  by  the  following  formal  treaty  as  to  new  appli- 
ances, etc.  :  "  Notwithstanding  any  of  the  above  clauses  the 
shipbuilders  are  to  be  entitled  to  a  revision  of  rates  on 
account  of  labor-saving  appliances,  whether  now  existing 
and  not  sufficiently  allowed  for,  or  hereafter  to  be  intro- 
duced ;  for  improved  arrangements  in  yards  ;  for  rates  to 
be  paid  in  vessels  of  new  types  where  work  is  easier,  and 
for  other  special  cases.  The  terms  of  these  revisions  to  be 
adjusted  by  a  committee  representing  employers  and  the 
Boilermakers'  and  Shipbuilders'  Society.  The  men  shall  in 
like  manner  be  entitled  to  bring  before  the  said  committee 
any  jobs,  the  rates  of  which  may  require  revision  due  to  new 
conditions  of  working,  structural  alterations  in  vessels,  or 
any  other  cause."  This  agreement  met  with  some  opposi- 
tion from  a  section  of  the  workmen,  who  objected  to  any 
allowances  being  made  for  machinery,  etc.  To  this  com- 
plaint the  Executive  Committee  of  the  union  replied  :  "  It 
is  well  known  to  the  oldest  shipyard  plater  in  our  society 
that  he  can  go  into  some  yards  and  plate  a  vessel  at  10 
per  cent  per  plate  less  in  one  yard  than  he  can  in  another 
on  account  of  the  difference  in  machinery.  The  employer 
therefore  who  has  the  best  machinery  is  being  paid  for  his 
machines  through  having  his  work  done  at  a  cheaper  rate. 
.  .  .  This  is  done  all  over,  and  rightly  so.  It  is  well  known 
to  our  platers  that,  on  account  of  the  difference  of  facilities 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  4 1 1 

for  doing  work  in  the  different  yards,  we  have  never  been 
able  to  get  a  standard  list  of  prices  for  plating."  l 

We  may  now  sum  up  what  seems  to  us  the  outcome  of 
Trade  Union  experience  in  dealing  with  new  processes  and 
machinery,  and  what,  judging  from  the  general  tendency 
and  the  example  of  the  Cotton  Operatives,  may_be  expected 
to  becojme_the  universaljjolicy.  We  see,  in  the  first  place,  / 
that  the  old  attempt  of  the  handicraftsman  to  exclude  the  1 
machine  has  been  definitely  abandoned.  Far  from  refusing' 
to  work  the  new  processes,  the  Trade  Unionists  of  to-day 
claim,  for  the  operatives  already  working  at  the  trade,  a 
preferential  right  to  acquire  the  new  dexterity  and  perform 
the  new  service.  In  asserting  this  preferential  claim  to 
continuity  of  employment,  they  insist  that  the  arrangements 
for  introducing  the  new  process,  including  not  only  the  rates 
of  wages  but  also  the  physical  conditions  of  work,  are 
matters  to  be  settled,  not  solely  by  one  of  the  parties  to  the 
wage  contract,  but  after  discussion  between  both  of  them 
Moreover,  on  the  principle  of  Collective  Bargaining,  the 
matter  is  not  one  which  can  be  left  even  to  agreement 
between  any  particular  employer  and  his  workpeople,  but 
one  which  must  be  settled  by  negotiation,  as  a  Common  Rule 
to  be  enforced  on  all  employers  and  operatives  in  the 
particular  trade.2  When  this  Collective  Bargaining  takes 
place,  the  Trade  Union  always  proceeds  on  the  fundamental 
assumption  that  under  no  circumstances  must  the  "  improve- 
ment "  be  allowed  to  put  the  operative  in  any  worse  position 
than  he  was  before.  The  change  of  technical  process, 
which  may  revolutionise  all  the  conditions  of  this  working 

1  Monthly  Report  of  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers  and  Iron -shipbuilders, 
January  1895. 

2  This  claim,  to  make  the  circumstances  under  which  a  change  of  process 
shall  take  place  a  matter  for  Collective  Bargaining,  has  only  lately  been  admitted, 
or  even  comprehended  by  employers  ;  and  the  demand  would,  in  many  trades, 
still  be   regarded  as  preposterous.      Until    1871,   indeed,  combination  for  any 
other  objects  than  improvement  in  wages  or  hours  was  a  criminal  offence,  and  it 
nsver  occurred,  even  to  a  good  employer,  that  the  most  momentous  change  in 
the  method  of  working  could  be  a  matter  for  mutual  arrangement  between  his 
workpeople  and  himself. 


412  Trade  Union  Fimction 

life,  is  calculated  greatly  to  increase  the  productivity  of  his 
labor,  and  should,  it  is  claimed,  at  any  rate  not  be  made  the 
occasion  of  any  encroachment  on  the  privileges  or  advan- 
tages which  he  has  hitherto  enjoyed.  This  involves,  not 
only  that  his  weekly  earnings  shall  be  maintained,  but  also 
that  the  length  of  the  working  day,  the  amount  of  physical 
or  mental  exertion  required  by  his  task,  or  the  discomfort  or 
disagreeableness  of  his  work  shall  either  not  be  increased,  or 
else  that  any  increase  shall  be  fully  paid  for  by  extra  rates. 
It  will,  moreover,  be  demanded  that  any  defensive  or  other 
regulations,  which  have  hitherto  been  accepted,  shall  be 
continued  and  made  applicable  to  the  new  conditions.  The 
pieceworker  will  expect  a  definitely  settled  detailed  list  of 
prices  ;  the  timeworker  will  require  any  accustomed  protec- 
tion against  being  "  driven "  beyond  the  normal  speed, 
whilst  in  trades  in  which  apprenticeship  has  hitherto  been 
regulated  a  continuance  of  the  regulation  will  be  insisted 
on.1  All  this  merely  comes  to  a  demand  that  the  condition 
and  status  of  the  workman  should  not  be  deteriorated  by 
Ithe  change  which  is  to  bring  a  new  profit  to  the  employer. 
To  this  there  will  sometimes  be  added  the  further  claim 
which  stands,  it  is  obvious,  on  a  different  footing,  that  the 
wage-earner  should  receive  some  of  the  advantages  to  be 
derived  from  the  improvement,  and  that  he  should  therefore 
take  the  opportunity  of  obtaining,  as  a  condition  of  his 
acceptance  of  the  new  process,  some  positive  increase  in  his 
Standard  Rate. 

1  Comfort  and  habits  of  life  often  play  an  important  part  in  these  negotiations, 
leading  sometimes  to  obstruction,  sometimes  to  encouragement  of  a  change. 
Thus  the  Yorkshire  Glass  Bottle  Makers'  Society  refused  in  1875  to  work  with 
a  new  gas  furnace,  because  they  declared  it  would  involve  a  three-shift  system ; 
an  objection  paralleled  by  the  Northumberland  and  Durham  miners'  refusal  to 
shorten  the  hours  of  boys,  because  it  will  probably  involve  a  change  from  two 
to  three  shifts.  In  both  cases  the  men  assert  that  the  alteration  of  hours  would 
be  inconvenient  and  unpleasant  to  them.  On  the  other  hand,  when  in  1876  a 
new  system  of  "  pot-setting  "  was  invented  in  the  glass  trade,  which  was  safer 
and  more  rapid  than  the  old  process,  the  Yorkshire  Glass  Bottle  Makers'  Society 
passed  a  resolution  demanding  its  adoption,  and  insisting  on  those  firms  which 
still  retained  the  old  plan  paying  2s.  per  man  for  the  operation,  as  compared 
with  only  6d.  for  the  new  system. — See  the  Annual  Reports  of  the  Yorkshire 
Glass  Bottle  Makers'  Society  for  1875  and  1876. 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  4 1 3 

It  is  interesting  to  observe  that,  with  the  acceptance  of  this 
new  policy  by  the  employers,  and  its  complete  comprehension 
by  the  workmen,  it  is  not  the  individual  capitalist,  but  the 
Trade  Union,  which  most  strenuously  insists  on  having  the 
very  latest  improvements  in  machinery.  In  the  English 
boot  and  shoe  trade,  every  improvement  is,  as  we  have  seen, 
made  the  occasion  of  a  prolonged  wrangle  between  employers 
and  workmen.  In  Lancashire  it  quickly  becomes  a  grievance 
in  the  Cotton  Trade  Unions,  if  any  one  employer  or  any  one 
district  falls  behind  the  rest.  The  explanation  of  this  differ- 
ence is  obvious.  No  employer  takes  any  trouble  to  induce 
the  laggards  in  his  own  industry  to  keep  up  with  the  march 
of  invention.  Their  falling  behind  is,  indeed,  an  immediate 
advantage  to  himself.  But  to  the  Trade  Union,  repre- 
senting all  the  operatives,  the  sluggishness  of  the  poor  or 
stupid  employers  is  a  serious  danger.  The  old-fashioned 
master  spinners,  with  slow-going  family  concerns,  complain 
bitterly  of  the  harshness  with  which  the  Trade  Union 
officials  refuse  to  make  any  allowance  for  their  relatively 
imperfect  machinery,  and  even  insist,  as  we  have  seen,  on 
their  paying  positively  a  higher  piecework  rate  if  they  do 
not  work  their  mills  as  efficiently  as  their  best -equipped 
competitors.  Thus,  the  Amalgamated  Association  of 
Operative  Cotton -spinners,  instead  of  obstructing  new 
machinery,  actually  penalises  the  employer  who  fails  to 
introduce  it !  This  remarkable  difference,  in  the  attitude 
of  both  workmen  and  employers,  between  the  two  great 
English  industries  of  cotton-spinning  and  bootmaking,  goes 
far  to  explain  their  very  different  standing  as  regards 
technical  efficiency.  The  English^  boot  manufacturer  is 
always  complaining  of  the  far  higher  efficiency  of  the 
splendidly -equipped  factories  of  Massachusetts  and  Con- 
necticut. The  Lancashire  cotton  mill,  in  the  amount  of 
output  per  operative,  easily  leads  the  world. 

There  remains  one  other  type  of  case  to  be  dealt  with, 
namely  that  in  which  the  new  process,  instead  of  being 
worked  by  the  old  skilled  hands,  supersedes  them  by  a  class 


414  Trade  Union  Function 

of  entire  novices.  As  this  happens  to  be  the  very  type 
which,  from  its  association  with  tragic  episodes  in  industrial 
history,  strikes  the  public  imagination  most  forcibly,  and  has 
accordingly  become  a  commonplace  in  the  denunciations  of 
our  industrial  system  from  the  more  extreme  platforms  of 
social  reform,  its  omission,  so  far,  may  have  struck  the 
reader  as  an  unexpected  oversight.  It  is  possible  for  the 
introduction  of  a  new  machine  or  process  to  annihilate  the 
utility  of  a  workman's  skill  as  completely  as  the  photograph 
has  annihilated  the  miniature,  the  railway  train  the  stage 
coach,  or  petroleum  the  snuffers.  The  heart-rending  struggle 
of  the  handloom  weavers  against  the  power  loom  is  perhaps 
the  best-known  instance.  Let  us  follow,  step  by  step,  or 
rather  stumble  by  stumble,  the  road  to  ruin  of  an  in- 
sufficiently organised  trade  supplanted  by  machinery.1 

When  the  handicraftsman  begins  to  find  his  product 
undersold  by  the  machine-made  article,  his  first  instinct  is 
to  engage  in  a  desperate  competition  with  the  new  process, 
lowering  his  rate  for  hand  labor  to  keep  pace  with  the 
diminished  cost  of  the  machine  product.  This  is  obviously 
the  "line  of  least  resistance."  No  newly-devised  machine, 
worked  by  novices,  and  not  yet  perfectly  adapted  to  the 
process,  can  convince  a  skilled  handworker  that  it  will 
ever  succeed  in  turning  out  as  good  an  article  as  he  can 
make,  or  that  the  saving  of  time  will  be  at  all  considerable. 
The  very  fact  that  a  lad  or  a  girl  at  ten  or  fifteen  shillings 
a  week  can  perform  the  new  process  with  ease,  only  con- 
firms him  in  his  attitude  of  disparagement  and  incredulity. 

1  The  struggle  of  the  small  hand  industry  against  the  factory  system  can  be 
best  studied  at  present  in  Germany  and  Austria,  where  the  position  is  being 
described  in  detail  by  scores  of  competent  observers.  See,  among  other  studies, 
Professor  Gustav  Schmoller's  Zur  Geschichte  der  Deutschen  Kleingewerbe  im  ityh 
fahrhundert  (Halle,  1870);  Dr.  Eugen  Schwiedland's  Kleingewerbe  tind  Haus- 
industrie  in  Oesterreich  (Leipzig,  1894),  2  vols.  ;  and  his  two  Reports  Ueber  eine 
gesetzliche  Regelung  der  Heimarbeit  (Vienna,  1896  and  1897)  ;  Dr.  Kuno 
Frankenstein's  Die  Deutsche  Hausindustrie^  4  vols.  ;  the  article  "  Hausindustrie  " 
by  Prof.  Werner  Sombart  in  Conrad's  Handworterbuch  der  Staatswissenschaften, 
vol.  iv.  ;  and  the  magnificent  series  of  monographs  on  particular  trades  or 
districts,  published  by  the  "Verein  fur  Sozial  Politik  "  as  Untersuchungen  uber 
die  Lage  des  Handwerks  in  Deutschland  (Leipzig,  1894-97),  12  volumes. 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  4 1 5 

In  such  a  mood  a  man  does  not  throw  away  the  skill  which 
is  his  property  and  staff  of  life,  to  consent  to  become  either 
a  machine-minder  at  one-half  or  one -third  of  his  accustomed 
wages,  or  else  begin  life  afresh  in  some  entirely  new 
occupation.  He  confidently  pits  his  consummate  skill 
against  the  first  clumsy  attempts  of  the  undeveloped  machine, 
and  finds  that  a  slight  reduction  in  the  Standard  Rate  for 
hand  labor  is  all  that  seems  required  to  leave  his  handi- 
craft in  full  command  of  the  market.  His  well-intentioned 
friends,  the  clergyman  and  the  district  visitor,  the  news- 
paper economist  and  the  benevolent  employer,  combine 
to  assure  him  that  this — the  Policy  of  Lowering  the  Dyke 
— is  what  he  ought  to  adopt.  But,  unfortunately,  this  is  to 
enter  on  a  downward  course  to  which  there  is  no  end.  The 
machine  product  steadily  improves  in  quality,  and  falls  in 
price,  as  the  new  operatives  become  more  skilled,  and  as  the 
speed  of  working  is  increased.  Every  step  in  this  evolution 
means  a  further  reduction  of  rates  to  the  struggling  hand- 
worker, who  can  only  make  up  his  former  earnings  by 
hurrying  his  work  and  lengthening  his  hours.  Inevitably 
this  hurry  and  overwork  deteriorate  the  old  quality  and 
character  of  his  product.  The  attempt  to  maintain  his 
family  in  its  old  position  compels  him  to  sacrifice  everything 
to  the  utmost  possible  rapidity  of  execution.  His  wife  and 
children  are  pressed  into  his  service,  and  a  rough  and  ready 
division  of  labor  serves  to  economise  the  use  of  the  old 
thought  and  skill.  The  work  insidiously  drops  its  artistic 
quality  and  individual  character.  In  the  losing  race  with 
the  steam  engine,  the  handwork  becomes  itself  mechanical, 
without  acquiring  either  that  uniform  excellence  or  accurate 
finish  which  is  the  outcome  of  the  perfected  machine. 
Presently,  the  degraded  hand  product  will  sell  only  at  a 
lower  price  than  the  machine-made  article.  The  worse  the 
work  becomes  the  more  irregular  grows  the  demand. 
Those  select  customers,  who  have  remained  faithful  to  the 
hand  product,  find,  by  degrees,  that  its  former  qualities  have 
departed,  and  they  one  by  one  accept  the  modern  substitute. 


416  Trade  Union  Function 

And  thus  we  reach  the  vicious  circle  of  the  sweated  in- 
dustries, in  which  the  gradual  beating  down  of  the  rate  of 
remuneration  produces  an  inevitable  deterioration  in  the 
quality  of  the  work,  whilst  the  inferiority  of  the  product 
itself  makes  it  unsaleable  except  at  prices  which  compel  the 
payment  of  progressively  lower  rates.  The  handworker, 
who  at  the  beginning  justifiably  felt  himself  on  a  higher 
level  than  the  mechanical  minder  of  the  machine,  ends  by 
sinking,  in  physique  and  dexterity  alike,  far  below  the  level 
of  the  highly-strung  factory  operative.  There  is  now  no 
question  of  his  taking  to  the  new  process,  which  has 
risen  quite  beyond  his  capacity.  He  passes  through  the 
long-drawn-out  agony  of  a  dying  trade. 

This,  in  main  outline,  is  the  story  of  the  handloom 
weavers  in  all  the  branches  of  the  textile  industry.1  We  see 
the  same  grim  evolution  going  on  to-day  in  the  chain  and 
nail  trade  in  the  Black  Country,  and  among  the  unorganised 
sections  of  the  tailors  and  cabinetmakers.  We  need  not 
dilate  on  the  misery  to  which  these  unfortunate  workers  are 
reduced.  But  it  is  important  to  observe  how  the  interests 
of  the  consumers  are  affected  by  this  "  Policy  of  Lowering 
the  Dyke."  It  is,  in  the  first  place,  to  be  noted  that  it  in  no 
way  stimulates  the  spread  of  machinery  or  the  perfecting  of 
the  new  process.  The  constant  yielding  of  the  handworker 
even  diminishes  the  pressure  on  his  employer  to  adopt  the 
newest  improvements,  and  positively  tempts  him  to  linger 
on  with  the  old  process.  So  long  as  he  can  compete  with 
his  rival  by  another  cut  off  wages,  it  will  not  seem  worth 
while  to  lay  out  capital  and  thought  in  new  machinery. 
Thus,  the  transition  from  the  old  system  of  production  to 
the  improved  methods  is  delayed,  to  the  loss  of  the  consumer 
for  the  time  being.  But  what  is  perhaps  of  greater  import- 
ance to  the  community  is  the  disappearance  of  any  real 

1  "Heartbroken  and  objectless  in  their  squalid  poverty,  their  insight  into  the 
active  stirring  world  beyond  them,  with  its  various  moving  springs  and  wires, 
became  perverted,  and  they  stuck  to  their  falling  trade  with  a  kind  of  obstinate 
fatalism." — John  Hill  Burton,  Political  and  Social  Economy  (Edinburgh,  1849), 
p.  29. 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  417 

alternative  to  the  machine  product.  The  degradation  of  the 
handworker's  craft,  resulting,  as  we  have  seen,  directly  from 
the  forcing  down  of  his  Standard  Rate,  deprives  the  nation 
of  the  charm  given  to  the  old  country  stuffs  and  furniture 
by  their  artistic  individuality.  Even  the  machine-made 
product  is  the  worse  for  the  deterioration  of  the  handicraft. 
It  gradually  loses  the  ideal  of  perfect  workmanship  and 
artistic  finish,  to  which  the  inventor  and  operative  were 
perpetually  striving  to  approximate.  It  is,  indeed,  difficult 
to  discover  any  advantage  whatsoever,  either  to  the  handi- 
craftsman or  to  the  community,  in  a  policy  which,  whilst 
failing  to  stimulate  the  use  of  labor-saving  machinery, 
neither  saves  the  handworkers  from  misery,  nor  preserves  to 
the  community  what  is  of  value  in  their  handicraft. 

Here,  then,  we  have  the  dramatic  instance  as  it  actually 
occurs  ;  and  certainly  the  reality  is  as  harrowing  as  the  most 
fervidly  descriptive  platform  orator  can  make  it  appear.  And 
yet  its  tragedy  is  incomplete  without  the  final  demonstration 
that  the  really  cruel  stages  of  all  this  suffering  are  needless, 
and  are  caused  not  by  the  iron  march  of  industrial  evolution, 
but  simply  by  the  adoption  on  the  part  of  the  workmen  and 
their  employers  of  this  "  Policy  of  Lowering  the  Dyke."  We 
have  failed  to  discover  a  single  instance  of  supersession  by 
machinery,  in  which  it  would  not  have  been  possible  for  the 
superseded  handicraft  at  least  to  have  died  a  painless  death. 
There  are  industries  which  have  been  changed  by  machinery 
as  thoroughly  as  weaving,  but  in  which,  owing  to  the  enforce- 
ment ot  a  different  policy  by  the  Trade  Unions  concerned, 
the  handworkers  have  not  only  survived,  but  are  to-day 
busier,  more  highly  paid,  and  more  skilful  than  ever  they 
were  before. 

The  Amalgamated  Society  of  Cordwainers,  an  organisa- 
tion dating  from  the  eighteenth  century,1  had,  up  to  1857, 
enjoyed  a  complete  immunity  from  any  invasion  by  machinery 

1  See  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  p.  51,  where  a  circular  of  1784  is  quoted. 
The  organisation  was  reformed  in  1862,  and  in  1874  it  took  the  name  of  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Makers. 

VOL.  I  2  E 


4i 8  Trade  Union  Function 

or  new  processes.  The  application  of  the  sewing-machine  to 
bootmaking,  and  the  successive  introduction  of  new  inven- 
tions led,  between  1857  and  1874,  to  a  complete  revolution 
in  the  trade.  At  first  the  rank  and  file  of  the  workmen 
bitterly  resented  the  change  of  conditions,  and  the  employer 
introducing  a  new  machine  was  often  met  by  the  most 
unreasonable  demands.  But  the  Executive  Committee  of 
the  Trade  Union,  whilst  maintaining  intact  the  established 
scale  of  prices  for  handwork,  steadfastly  refused  to  sanction 
any  resistance  to  the  new  processes.  On  the  contrary,  it 
persistently  advised  all  its  members  who  failed  to  get  hand- 
work at  the  established  high  rates,  to  accept  employment  at 
the  new  factories  at  whatever  they  could  get,  and  gradually 
to  work  out  a  new  piecework  list  adapted  to  the  altered 
conditions.  In  order  to  secure  this  fresh  "  Statement " 
these  members  were  advised  to  join  hands  with  the  new  men 
whom  the  factory  brought  into  the  trade,  and  freely  to  admit 
them  into  their  branches.  Thus,  already  in  1863,  it  was 
resolved  "that  men  employed  in  the  rivetting  and  finishing 
peg-work,  and  those  working  in  factories,  be  recognised,  and 
can  belong  to  any  section,  or  form  sections  by  themselves."1 
This  policy,  pressed  on  the  members  at  every  opportunity, 
was  quickly  accepted,  with  the  result  that  the  union  found 
itself,  in  a  very  few  years,  composed  of  two  distinct  classes 
of  membeis,  handicraftsmen  and  factory  workers.  When 

1  The  Trade  Sick  and  Funeral  Lavas  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Cord- 
wainers  (London,  1863).  The  "rivetters"  became  a  separate  class,  when, 
about  1846,  rivetting  was  introduced  in  place  of  stitching.  See  the  manifesto  of 
the  Leicester  shoemakers,  quoted  by  Marx,  Capital,  Part  IV.  chap.  xv.  sec.  7 
(vol.  ii.  p.  457  of  English  translation  of  1887).  The  operatives  in  the  factory 
boot  manufacture  are  at  present  divided  into  the  following  classes:  (i)  the 
"  clickers,"  the  men  and  lads  who  cut  from  skins  the  sections  of  the  boot  and 
uppers;  (2)  "  rough  -stuff  cutters,"  the  men  who  cut  the  bottom  material  by 
knives  set  in  powerful  machines;  (3)  "fitters,"  men  who  place  the  upper 
leathers  in  position  for  "  closing  ";  (4)  "  machinists  "  (often  women)  who  "  close  " 
or  stitch  the  uppers;  (5)  Blasters,"  men  or  boys  who  place  the  closed  uppers 
over  the  last  and  attach  the  bottom  material  (in  hand-sewn  work  these  are  known 
as  "  makers,"  in  "  pegged  work,"  now  nearly  obsolete,  they  are  called  "  pegmen  " 
or  "rivetters");  (6)  the  "finishers,"  who  blacken  the  edges,  clean  the  soles, 
and  generally  polish  up  the  boot.  The  two  latter  classes  form  a  large  majority 
of  the  whole. 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  4 1 9 

the  latter  began  actually  to  outnumber  their  old-fashioned 
colleagues,  it  was  found  convenient,  as  we  have  already 
mentioned,  that  they  should  break  off,  and  form  a  society  of 
their  own,  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives. 
The  Amalgamated  Society  of  Cordwainers,  now  again  con- 
fined to  the  handicraftsmen,  has  ever  since  continued  to 
pursue  the  same  line  of  policy.  It  has  remained  on  amicable 
terms  with  the  new  society,  neither  competing  with  it  for 
members,  nor  in  any  way  obstructing  its  remarkable  growth. 
But  what  is  more  important,  it  has  steadfastly  refused  to 
allow  its  own  members  to  compete  in  cheapness  with  the  new 
process.  If  a  handmade  boot  is  desired,  the  old  scale  for 
handwork  must  be  paid.  Many  consequences  have  resulted 
from  this  policy,  some  of  which  might  not,  at  first  sight, 
have  been  expected.  As  the  employers  found  no  way  of 
getting  a  commoner  class  of  boots  made  by  inferior  hand 
labor  at  low  rates,  machinery  has  gone  ahead  by  leaps  and 
bounds.  But  it  has  created  an  entirely  new  trade  for  itself. 
The  keeping  up  of  a  high  level  of  price  for  the  handmade 
article  has  not  destroyed  the  demand,  but  has,  on  the  con- 
trary, given  it  permanence  and  stability.  The  employers, 
rinding  themselves  bound  in  any  case  to  pay  the  old  scale  of 
rates,  have  had  to  concentrate  their  attention  on  obtaining 
the  finest  possible  workmanship,  as  only  in  this  way  were 
they  able  to  tempt  their  customers  to  prefer  the  necessarily 
expensive  handmade  product.  Those  persons  who  are  pre- 
pared to  pay  well  for  first-class  workmanship  find  therefore 
that  they  can  still  obtain  exactly  what  they  require,  and 
hence  remain  faithful  to  the  handmade  boot.  Meanwhile, 
the  handicraftsmen  have  become  a  select  body,  not  because 
they  have  closed  their  ranks,  but  because  none  but  men  of 
long  training  and  exceptional  skill  can  find  employment  at 
the  recognised  scale,  or  do  the  highly-finished  work  which 
the  employers  require  in  return  for  such  high  rates.  Com- 
petition between  the  handicraftsmen  takes,  in  fact,  the  form 
of  a  continuous  elimination  of  the  less  skilled  among  them, 
who  are  encouraged,  in  their  youth,  to  go  into  the  machine 


420  Trade  Union  Function 

trade.  The  result  has  been  that  the  skilled  hand  boot- 
makers, whilst  somewhat  diminishing  in  numbers,  have 
positively  improved  their  scale  of  prices  and  average  earn- 
ings, and  more  than  maintained  their  level  of  skill.  Finally, 
notwithstanding  a  continuous  improvement  in  the  efficiency 
of  bootmaking  machinery,  the  handmade  boot  still  remains 
an  ideal  to  which  inventors  and  factory  managers  are  per- 
petually striving  to  approximate  their  commoner  product. 

This  analysis  of  the  policy  of  the  Amalgamated  Society 
of  Boot  and  Shoe  Makers  finds  a  remarkable  confirmation 
in  the  analogous  case  of  the  paper  manufacturers.  A  gener- 
ation ago  this  old  trade  of  skilled  handworkers,  closely 
combined  since  the  middle  of  the  eighteenth  century,1  was 
seriously  menaced  by  the  rapid  spread  of  machine-made 
paper.  Foreign  competition,  too,  began,  on  the  repeal  of  the 
paper  duty  in  1861,  to  cut  into  the  trade  of  the  English 
manufacturers,  and  the  United  Kingdom,  from  being  a  large 
exporter  of  paper,  gradually  became  a  large  importer.  The 
hand  papermakers,  who  had,  from  time  immemorial,  enjoyed 
wages  15  or  20  per  cent  higher  than  those  even  of  skilled 
artisans  in  other  trades,  made  no  attempt  to  prevent  or  to 
discourage  the  introduction  of  paper-making  machinery,  or 
even  to  secure  the  new  work  for  their  own  members.  The 
machine-workers  were  at  first  admitted  to  membership  of 
the  handworkers'  union,  but  few  of  them  joined,  and  (as  in 
the  analogous  case  of  the  boot  and  shoe  operatives)  it  was 
afterwards  found  more  convenient  for  the  new  class  of  work- 
men to  form  organisations  of  their  own.2  The  highly-paid 

1  "  Our  Society,"  said  the  spokesman  of  the  Original  Society  of  Papermakers 
in   1891,  "can  go  back,  according  by  the  records,  to  150  or  160  years."     Its 
very  archaic  rules,  preserved  in  the  appendix  to  the  Report  of  the   Committee 
on  Combinations  of  Workmen^    1825,  are  referred  to  in  the  History  of  Trade 
Unionism,  p.  80. 

2  It  was  stated  in  evidence  in  1874  that  "the  Society  is  composed  of  some 
700  men,  of  whom  420  are  employed  in  vat  mills,"  the  former  comprising  a  very 
large  proportion  of  the  entire   handmade  trade,  and  the  latter  only  a  triflim 
proportion  of  the  machine  trade  (Report  of  Arbitration  on  the  Question  of  an 
Advance  in  Wages  .   .   .    loth  July  1874,  Maidstone,  1874,  p.  53).      At  present 
(1897)  the  machinemen  are  organised  in  two  separate  unions,  the  Amalgamated 
Society  of  Papermakers,  a  strong  body  in  the  South  of  England,  and  the  National 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  421 

handworkers  were  incessantly  advised  to  moderate  their 
demands,  so  as  to  enable  their  employers  to  compete  with 
the  new  machine  mills,  which  started  up  in  every  county. 
As  early  as  1864  a  leading  employer  gave  them  an  ominous 
warning.  "  When  you  see  .  .  ."  he  said,  "  regular  machine 
mills  (such  as  I  intend  to  stand  by,  if  driven  from  the  vats) 
rising  up  around  you  .  .  .  remember  the  old  fable  of  '  The 
Goose  with  the  Golden  Eggs '  .  .  .  lest  .  .  .  you  lose  the 
position  in  which  you  now  stand."  l  "  How  can  we  compete 
with  the  machine  paper  unless  wages  are  reduced  ?  "  asked 
a  millowner  in  1891.  "I  say  the  best  course  for  you  to 
adopt,"  replied  the  spokesman  of  the  operatives,  "  is  to  keep 
up  the  quality  and  the  price  of  handmade  paper." 2  This 
policy  has  been  consistently  pursued  by  the  Trade  Union. 
Far  from  consenting  to  lower  its  members'  rates  of  pay,  it 
has  taken  every  opportunity  to  raise  them.  "  We  have  never 
had  a  reduction  of  wages  in  the  paper  trade,"  declared  the 
men's  secretary  in  1 874.®  "In  1839,"  a  leading  employer 
told  the  arbitrator,  "  there  was  an  increase  of  wages,  in  1853 
a  slight  modification,  in  1854  a  slight  increase,  another 
increase  in  1865,  in  1869  a  slight  increase,  when  beer  money 
was  given  instead  of  beer.  ...  So  we  went  on  from  1838 
to  1872,  giving  these  three  or  four  rises,  and,  in  1872,  a  rise 
of  sixpence  per  day  was  conceded  by  the  employers  without 
any  great  fuss " ; 4  the  pay  of  a  first-class  vatman  for  a  "  day's 
work"  in  a  Kentish  mill  being  now  6s.  5d.,  as  compared 
with  45.  7d.  in  i84O.5  It  is  interesting  to  find  the  workmen 
expressly  comparing  their  own  attitude  with  that  of  the 

Union  of  Paper  Mill  Workers  of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland,  a  weaker  society 
with  membership  chiefly  in  the  North  of  England  and  in  Scotland. 

1  Notes  of  Proceedings  at  a  Meeting  of  Paper  Manufacturers  and  Journeymen 
Papermakers  Relative  to  an  Advance  in  Wages  (Maidstone,  1864),  p.  34. 

2  Report  of  Arbitration  Meeting  between  Employers  and  Employed  in  the 
Handmade  Paper  Trade  ...  on  29th  January  1891  (Maidstone,  1891),  p.  65. 

3  Arbitration  Report  of  1874,  pp.  14,  17.      "Never  once  in  the  history  of 
the   trade  had  there  been  a  reduction   of  the  prices." — Report  of  Meeting  of 
Employers  and  Employed  ...  on  1 5th  September  1884   (Maidstone,   1884), 
p.  1 8. 

4  Arbitration  Report  of  1891,  pp.  45-46. 

6  See  table  of  rates  in  the  Arbitration  Report  of  1874,  p.  33. 


I 


422  Trade  Union  Function 

Amalgamated  Society  of  Cordwainers,  and  justifying  it  on 
the   same   grounds.      "  There    is    no   doubt,"    declared   their 
spokesman  in  1891,  "that  handmade  paper  will  continue  to 
hold  its  own  in  the  market.     There  are  now  many  branches 
of  industry  where  machines  play  a  very  important  part  in 
the  production  of  various  goods.  .  .  .  [But]  if  you  want  a 
splendid  article  in  those  materials,  you  must  have  handmade. 
.  .  .  The  same   remark   applies   to   the   shoemaking   trade. 
Handmade    shoemakers  now  command  higher  wages  than 
ever  they  did   in   the   history  of  the  trade.     Their  services 
have  become  much  more  important  and  valuable  since  the 
introduction  of  machines,  which  now  manufacture  all  parts 
and  all  kinds  of  shoes.      The  people  know  that  if  they  want 
a  good  boot  they  must  have  handmade.      It  seems  to  me 
.  .  .  that  handmade  paper  is  precisely  in  the  same  position. 
If  people  want  the  genuine  article  they  will,  notwithstandinj 
the  cost,   go  in  for  handmade   paper." l     That  this  policy 
has,  in  the  paper  trade,  been  attended  by  success  is  admittt 
on  all  sides.     The  rigid  maintenance  of  high  rates  for  hand- 
made paper  has  given  the  utmost  possible  encouragement  t< 
the  introduction    of  machinery,  wherever  machinery  could 
possibly  be  employed.      The   production   of  machine-mad< 
paper  has  accordingly  advanced  by  leaps  and  bounds,  to  th( 
great  advantage  of  the  public  in  the  cheapening  of  the  article 
for  common  use.      But  this  enormous  increase  of  productioi 
has  in  no  way  injured  the  trade  in  the  superior  handmade 
paper.      No  attempt  is  made  to  compete  in  cheapness  with 
the  machine-made  product,  the  manufacturers,  like  their  opera- 
tives, preferring  to  concentrate  their  attention   on   turning 
out  as  different  a  grade  of  quality  as  possible.     The  result 
has    been    in   the   highest    degree    remarkable.      Instead  of 
handmade  paper  mills  having  "  to  be  closed   all  over  the 
country,"  as  was  expected  in  1860,  it  was  reported  to  the 
arbitrator   that   by    1874  there   were   actually  considerably 
more  vats  at  work  than  had  ever  formerly  existed ;  that  by 
1891  the  number  of  vats  and  the  amount  of  the  sales  had 

1  Arbitration  Report  of  1891,  p.  10. 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  423 

still  further  increased  ;  and  that  "  the  last  sixteen  years  have 
been  the  most  successful  sixteen  years  that  we  have  ever  known 
in  the  trade." x  All  this  is  fully  conceded  by  the  employers. 
"The  masters,"  declared  their  spokesman  in  1891,  "never 
made  such  large  profits  in  the  old  days  as  they  have  made 
since.  I  admit  [that]  my  father,  for  instance,  who  had  a 
good  mill,  could  only  make  a  bare  living."  2  Meanwhile  the 
speed  and  continuity  of  the  work  has  been  steadily  increased, 
until  the  actual  output  in  pounds  of  paper  per  man  per  year 
in  the  best-equipped  mills  is  now  greater  than  it  has  ever 
been  in  the  history  of  the  craft.  The  prosperity  of  the 
employers,  as  their  leading  representative  explained  in  1891, 
"  has  been  due  to  two  causes.  In  the  first  place  there  has 
been — and  I  think  the  other  gentlemen  present  will  bear  me 
out  in  this — a  great  increase  of  sobriety  and  steadiness  on 
the  part  of  the  men.  There  was  a  time  when  they  did  not 
work,  sometimes  for  weeks  together,  five  days  a  week.  .  .  . 
That  is  one  great  cause  to  which  I  attribute  our  prosperity. 
.  .  .  The  other  cause  is  the  introduction  of  improvements  by 
the  masters.  The  mills  are  very  different  from  what  they 
used  to  be.  ...  It  is  easier  for  the  men  to  make  seven  days 
a  week  now  than  it  was  years  ago  to  make  six  days.  .  .  . 
Formerly  there  were  many  breakdowns  at  our  mills.  .  .  . 
All  these  things  have  been  changed."  3  We  see,  therefore, 
that  in  spite  of  the  adverse  influence  exercised,  as  we  shall 
show  in  a  later  chapter,  by  the  Trade  Union  Restriction  of 
Numbers  and  the  monopoly  enjoyed  by  the  old-established 
employers,  the  enforcement  of  a  high  Standard  of  Life  in  the 
handmade  paper  trade,  far  from  destroying  the  livelihood 
either  of  masters  or  men,  has  been  accompanied  by  a  marked 
advance  in  their  prosperity,  and  a  distinct  differentiation 
between  the  old  product  and  the  new.  The  policy  of  main- 
taining simultaneously  the  quality  and  the  price  of  the  hand- 

1  Arbitration  Report  of  1891,  p.  30.  2  Ibid.  p.  46. 

3  Ibid.  pp.  50-51.  In  the  handmade  paper  trade  "a  day's  work"  is  a 
definite  quantity  of  paper,  varying  according  to  size  and  weight.  It  has  no  relation 
to  the  period  of  employment. 


424  Trade  Union  Function 

made  article,  whilst  it*  has  given  a  positive  encouragement  to 
the  introduction  of  machinery  into  the  trade,  has  proved,  in 
fact,  the  salvation  of  the  hand  papermaker's  craft. 

Much  the  same  policy  has  been  pursued  by  the  Amalga- 
mated Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners  with  regard 
to  the  introduction  of  "ring-spinning,"  an  ingenious  appli- 
cation of  the  old  "  throstle-spinning,"  which  dates  from  about 
1 88 1.  By  the  substitution  of  the  "ring  frame"  for  the 
"  mule,"  it  has  been  found  possible,  in  the  manufacture  of 
certain  "  counts "  of  cotton  (the  coarser  "  twist "  up  to 
about  "So's"),  greatly  to  diminish  the  amount  of  skill 
and  effort  required.  What  formerly  demanded  the  con- 
centrated attention  of  a  highly -skilled  man  is  now  within 
the  capacity  of  an  untrained  woman.  Had  this  invention 
been  made  fifty  years  ago,  the  mule- spinners  would  un- 
doubtedly have  done  their  utmost  to  prevent  its  adoption, 
and  to  exclude  women  from  any  participation  in  cotton- 
spinning.  But  no  such  action  has  been  taken,  or  even 
suggested.  Although  the  Cotton -spinners'  Trade  Union, 
especially  in  its  close  alliance  with  the  Weavers  and  Cardroom 
Operatives,  now  exercises  a  far  more  effective  control  over 
the  industry  than  at  any  previous  period,  ring  spinning  by 
women  has,  during  the  last  fifteen  years,  been  allowed  to 
grow  up  unmolested.1  It  was  practically  impossible  for  the 
adult  male  spinners,  earning  two  pounds  a  week,  to  insist 
on  claiming  for  themselves  work  which  could  be  done  by 
women  at  fifteen  shillings  a  week.  But  they  might  have 
attempted  to  stave  off  the  innovation  by  lowering  the  rates 
for  their  own  work,  and  thereby  discouraging  their  employers 
from  making  the  change.  This,  as  we  have  seen,  was  the 
policy  followed  two  generations  ago  by  the  handloom  weavers. 
The  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners 
adopted  an  entirely  different  course.  When  an  employer 
complained  that  he  could  no  longer  compete  with  rivals  who 

1  The  ring-frame  spinners  were  even  received  into  the  Amalgamated  Associa- 
tion of  Card  and  Blowing  Room  Operatives,  with  the  full  assent  of  the  Spinners 
officials,  as  being  the  most  suitable  textile  organisation  for  them  to  join. 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  425 

had  adopted  the  ring  frame,  unless  his  mule-spinners  would 
accept  a  lower  rate,  he  was  told  that  under  no  circumstances 
could  any  "  lowering  of  the  dyke  "  be  permitted.  What  he 
was  offered  was,  as  we  have  described,  a  revision  of  the 
piecework  list  so  arranged  as  to  stimulate  him  to  augment 
the  rapidity  and  complexity  of  the  mule,  in  order  that  the 
mule-spinners,  increasing  in  dexterity,  might  simultaneously 
enlarge  the  output  per  machine  and  raise  their  own  earnings. 
The  cotton -spinners  in  short,  like  the  hand  bootmakers, 
preferred  to  meet  the  competition  of  a  new  process  by 
raising  their  own  level  of  skill,  rather  than  by  degrading 
their  Standard  of  Life.  The  result  has  been  that,  except 
under  certain  circumstances,  the  mule  has,  up  to  now,  fairly 
held  its  own.  The  number  of  mule-spinners,  like  the  number 
of  hand  bootmakers,  remains  about  stationary,  and  this 
without  the  slightest  attempt  or  desire  to  close  the  trade 
to  newcomers.  Like  the  bootmakers,  indeed,  the  mule- 
spinners  are  subject  to  a  constant  process  of  selection,  the 
employers  naturally  refusing  to  engage,  at  such  high  rates, 
any  but  the  most  skilled  men. 

There  is,  however,  one  point,  on  which  the  policy  of  the 
cotton-spinners  with  regard  to  the  ring  frame,  and  that  of  the 
papermakers  with  regard  to  the  machine,  has  fallen  short 
of  the  policy  of  the  hand  bootmakers  with  regard  to  the 
factory  system.  The  Amalgamated  Society  of  Cordwainers 
did  its  utmost,  as  we  have  seen,  to  organise  the  new  class  of 
factory  workers,1  so  that  these  could,  as  quickly  as  possible, 
secure  a  new  Standard  Rate  commensurate  with  the  skill 
and  effort  required.  This,  it  will  be  obvious,  is  really  a 
necessary  corollary  of  the  maintenance  of  a  Standard  Rate. 
The  adoption  of  a  new  process  must,  on  the  whole,  be 
deemed  an  advantage  to  the  community  when  it  effects  a 
real  saving  of  labor  or  economy  of  skill.  But  it  is  a  very 

1  "  That  clickers,  stuff-cutters,  pegmen,  finishers,  and  machinists  working  at 
the  shoe  trade  are  admitted  into  society.  That  all  women  working  at  the  shoe 
trade  be  admitted  into  the  Association  upon  the  same  terms,  and  entitled  to  the 
same  rights  of  membership  as  the  men." — Resolution  of  the  National  Union  o? 
Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives'  Conference,  i6th  September  1872. 


426  Trade  Union  Function 

different  thing  when  the  attractiveness  of  the  new  process  to 
the  employer  is  due,  not  to  any  real  economy  of  human 
labor,  but  to  the  chance  of  employing  a  helpless  class  of 
workers  at  starvation  wages.  Unless  the  workers  at  the 
new  process  are  paid  wages  sufficient  to  maintain  them  at 
the  required  new  level  of  skill  and  efficiency,  the  new  process 
must  be,  in  some  way,  parasitic  on  the  community.  To  give 
a  concrete  instance,  if  the  daughter  of  a  mule-spinner,  reared 
in  a  comparatively  comfortable  household,  and  maintained  at 
home  at  a  cost  of  fifteen  shillings  a  week,  offers  her  services  as 
a  ring-spinner  at  ten  shillings  a  week,  the  competition  between 
the  mule  and  the  ring  frame  may  reasonably  be  deemed 
"  unfair."  If  the  woman  had  to  live  on  the  ten  shillings, 
her  strength,  her  capacity  of  attention,  her  regularity  of 
attendance,  and  possibly  her  respectability,  would  inevitably 
degrade.  She  could,  moreover,  not  bring  up,  on  her  wages, 
a  new  generation  of  ring-spinners  to  replace  her.  So  long 
as  the  underpaid  worker  is  otherwise  partly  maintained — 
perhaps  the  most  usual  case  with  women  and  children — the 
employer  is,  in  effect,  receiving  a  bounty  in  favor  of  a 
particular  form  of  production,  and  the  community  has  no 
assurance  that  the  competition  between  the  processes  will 
lead  to  the  survival  of  the  fittest.  "  Whole  branches  of 
manufacture,"  to  use  the  weighty  words  of  the  Poor  Law 
Commission  of  1834,  "may  thus  follow  the  course,  not  of 
coal  mines  or  streams,  but  of  pauperism :  may  flourish 
like  the  fungi  that  spring  from  corruption,  in  consequence  of 
the  abuses  which  are  ruining  all  the  other  interests  of  the 
place  in  which  they  are  established,  and  cease  to  exist  in 
the  better  administered  districts  in  consequence  of  that  better 
administration." *  From  the  point  of  view  of  the  com- 
munity, therefore,  it  is  vital  that,  however  low  may  be  the 
standard  of  skill  and  strength  required  by  the  new  process, 
there  should  be  maintained  such  a  level  of  wages  as  will,  at 
any  rate,  fully  sustain  the  new  operatives  at  that  standard. 

1  First  Report  of  Poor  Law  Commissioners,  1834,   p.    65  of  reprint  of  1884 
(H.  C.  347). 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  427 

From  the  point  of  view  of  the  workers  at  the  old  process,  it 
is  clearly  of  the  utmost  consequence  that  the  new  process 
should  get  no  false  stimulus  by  such  a  "  bounty  "  as  we  have 
described. 

This  argument,  to  which  we  shall  recur  in  our  chapter 
on  "  The  Economic  Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism,"  is 
only  slowly  penetrating  into  the  minds  of  the  mule-spinners. 
Unlike  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Cordwainers,  the  Amal- 
gamated Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners  took  no 
trouble  to  organise  their  new  competitors,  the  women  ring- 
spinners,  to  whom  the  employers  were  allowed  to  pay  as 
little  as  they  pleased.  After  fifteen  years'  experience,  how- 
ever, this  idea  is  beginning  to  dawn  on  the  officials  of  the 
Cotton-spinners'  Union,  though  no  positive  action  can  yet 
be  recorded.1  But  it  has  never  yet  occurred  to  the  old- 
fashioned  close  corporation  of  hand  papermakers  that  they 
are  in  any  way  called  upon,  in  their  own  interest,  to  assist 
the  comparatively  unskilled  operatives  in  the  machine  paper- 
mills  of  the  North  of  England  to  secure  a  proper  Standard 
Rate.  And  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Tailors  never 
dreams  of  taking  steps  to  organise  the  ill-paid  women  of 
the  clothing  factories. 

We  see,  then,  that  where  skilled  labor  is  replaced  by 
unskilled,  the  paramount  importance  of  maintaining  the 
Standard  of  Life  warns  off  the  handworker,  both  from  any 
claim  to  work  the  new  process  and  from  any  attempt  to 
compete  in  cheapness  with  machine  work.  The  hand 
bootmakers,  the  hand  papermakers,  and  the  cotton  mule- 

1  Thus,  in  May  1896,  we  find  the  following  warning  note  in  the  organ  of  the 
Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners.  In  the  ring-frame 
spinning,  "employers  and  their  agents  have  practically  had  the  whole  field  to 
themselves  in  the  matter  of  fixing  prices  and  wages,  as  they  have  had  no  oppo- 
sition from  Trade  Unions  and  their  officials,  and  under  the  circumstances  they  have 
taken  great  care  to  pay  little  enough  for  the  labor  of  the  operatives  who  are 
employed  on  the  frames.  .  .  .  The  rapid  increase  of  this  class  of  spinning  is 
preventing  the  extension  of  mule-spinning,  and  so  damaging  the  future  prospects 
of  the  little  piecers  of  to-day.  The  Spinners'  Union  have  made  a  mistake  in  not 
paying  attention  to  getting  ring-spinners  as  members  of  their  association,  and 
framing  a  list  of  wages  to  govern  this  class  of  labor." — Cotton  Factory  2'imes, 
1 5th  May  1896. 


428  Trade  Union  Function 

spinners  have,  in  their  several  ways,  discovered  another 
policy,  viz. :  rigorously  to  enforce  the  old  high  rate  of  pay 
for  the  old  work,  frankly  to  abandon  to  the  machine  any 
part  of  the  trade  within  its  scope,  and  more  and  more  to 
concentrate  attention  on  maintaining  and  differentiating  the 
peculiar  qualities  of  their  own  special  article.  But  this 
enlightened  self-interest  requires,  from  the  economic  stand- 
point, to  be  supplemented  by  a  consideration  of  the  claims 
of  other  classes  of  operatives.  The  Trade  Unionist  is  begin- 
ning to  recognise  that  he  has  a  deep  interest  in  maintaining 
the  Standard  Rates  of  other  sections  of  workers.  The  logical 
outcome  of  Trade  Union  experience  in  all  these  difficult 
cases  seems,  indeed,  to  be  a  minimum  standard  of  remunera- 
tion for  effort,  whatever  the  grade  of  labor,  so  that,  under 
no  circumstances,  would  any  section  of  workers  find  itself 
reduced  below  the  level  of  complete  maintenance.1  Whenever 
an  employer  seeks  to  substitute  a  lower  for  a  higher  grade 
of  labor,  it  is  only  by  some  such  enforcement  of  a  minimum 
that  the  community  can  avoid  the  pernicious  bounty  to 
particular  occupations  or  processes,  irrespective  of  their 
social  advantageousness,  that  is  involved  in  the  labor  being 
partially  maintained  from  other  sources  than  its  wages.2 

1  We  must  refer  the  reader  for  a  full  explanation  of  this  difficult  point  of 
Trade  Union  theory  to  our  chapter  on  ' '  The  Economic  Characteristics  of  Trade 
Unionism." 

2  The  employers'  proposal  that  one  operative  should  attend  to  two  or  more 
machines  falls  economically  under  the  head  of  "speeding  up,"  rather  than  under 
that  of  a  change  of  process,  and  has  therefore  been  implicitly  dealt  with  in  our 
chapter  on  "The  Standard  Rate."     The  wage-earner's  traditional  resentment 
of  any  labor-saving  innovation  is  here  mingled  with  his  even  stronger  objection  to 
what  is  commonly  an  attempt  to  evade  the  Standard  Rate,  by  exacting  more 
bodily  exertion  or  mental  strain  for  the  same  money.     Thus  the  Carmen,  paid  by 
time,  at  a  rate  for  which  they  are  accustomed  to  mind  one  horse  and  cart, 
strongly  protest  against  one  man  being  required  to  attend  simultaneously  to  two 
vehicles.     The  same  feeling  influences  pieceworkers  unless  they  are  sufficiently 
protected  by  a  Standard  List  to  have  confidence  that  the  increase  in  the  day's 
task  and  earnings  will  not  be  followed  by  a  reduction  of  rates.     The  women 
cotton- weavers  of  Glasgow,  who  are  practically  unorganised,  and  whose  piecework 
rates,   unprotected  by  any  effective  list,  are  always  going  down  to  subsistence 
level,  stubbornly  refuse  to  work  more  than  one  loom  each.     The  cotton-weavers 
of  Lancashire,  on  the  other  hand,  whether  men  or  women,  relying  confidently  on 
their  strong  Trade   Union  and  their   Standard    Lists,  willingly  work  as  many 


New  Processes  and  Machinery  429 

looms — two,  four,  and  even  six — as  they  can  manage  (see  "  The  Alleged  Difference 
between  the  Wages  of  Men  and  Women,"  by  Sidney  Webb,  Economic  Journal ', 
December  1891).  The  employers'  attempt  to  induce  engineers  to  attend  to 
more  than  one  lathe  or  other  machine  has  led  to  much  friction.  In  this  instance 
it  is  not  clear  to  us  what  is  the  exact  issue.  If  it  is  suggested  that  the  engineer 
should,  for  the  weekly  wage  hitherto  paid  for  one  machine,  in  future  mind  two, 
the  case  is  merely  one  of  an  attempted  reduction  of  the  Standard  Rate,  which  the 
men  naturally  resist.  We  are  unable  to  gather  whether  the  employers  have 
made  it  plain  that  they  propose  to  increase  the  time  wages — say  to  time  and  a 
half — when  two  machines  are  minded,  or  whether  they  are  prepared  to  establish 
and  bind  themselves  to  adhere  to  a  Standard  List  of  piecework  rates,  which 
would  automatically  secure  to  the  operative  an  increase  in  earnings  proportionate 
to  the  increase  in  strain.  If  either  of  these  courses  were  adopted,  we  see  no 
reason  why  the  engineers  should  not,  like  the  cotton-weavers,  willingly  mind  as 
many  machines  as  they  can  without  undue  strain.  If  the  employers  claim  the 
right  to  assign  an  operative  to  as  many  machines  as  seems  fit  to  them,  without 
arranging  special  rates  with  the  Trade  Union  officials,  this  is  simply  a  denial  of 
the  elementary  right  of  Collective  Bargaining,  and  will  be  fought  as  such. 


CHAPTER    IX 

CONTINUITY    OF    EMPLOYMENT 

THE  Trade  Union  Regulations  which  we  have  described  in 
the  foregoing  chapters  have  dealt  exclusively  with  the  main- 
tenance and  improvement  of  the  conditions  of  employment : 
they  have  left  untouched  the  problem  of  unemployment.  A 
Standard  Rate,  a  Normal  Day,  and  safe  and  healthy  con- 
ditions of  work  are  of  no  avail  if  there  is  no  work  to  be  got. 
"We  are  willing  to  admit,"  said  the  Engineers  of  1851,  and 
the  Cloggers  of  1872,  "that  whilst  in  constant  employment 
our  members  may  be  able  to  obtain  the  necessaries  of  life. 
Notwithstanding  all  this,  there  is  always  a  fear  prominent 
in  the  mind  of  him  who  thinks  of  the  future  that  it  may 
not  continue  ;  that  to-morrow  may  see  him  out  of  employ- 
ment, his  nicely -arranged  matters  for  domestic  comfort 
overthrown,  and  his  hopes  of  being  able,  in  a  few  years,  by 
constant  attention  and  frugality  to  occupy  a  more  permanent 
position,  proved  only  to  be  a  dream.  How  much  is  contained 
in  that  word  '  continuance,'  and  how  necessary  to  make  it  a 
leading  principle  of  our  society  !  "  l  "  In  a  fluctuating  trade," 
say  the  Tailors,  "  many  who  depend  for  the  necessaries  of 
life  on  their  daily  toil  are  often  deprived  of  employment  in 
the  most  inclement  season.  They  wander  through  the 

1  Preface  to  Rules  and  Regulations  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers 
(London,  1851),  and  also  to  Rules  of  the  Rochdale  Operative  doggers'1  Society 
(Rochdale,  1872).  The  same  sentence  occurs,  with  verbal  variations,  in  other 
Trade  Union  rules.  (The  doggers  make  the  "clogs,"  or  wooden  shoes,  com- 
monly worn  in  the  streets  by  the  Lancashire  operatives.) 


Contin uity  of  Employment  4 3 1 

country  from  city  to  town,  and  from  town  to  village,  in 
search  of  employment,  but,  alas,  in  vain.  This  continues 
until,  upon  the  mind  of  an  honest  man,  the  thought  rests 
like  an  incubus,  When  and  how  shall  I  relieve  myself  of  this 
degradation  ?  " * 

We  touch  here  the  "  dead  point "  in  our  analysis  of 
Trade  Union  Regulations.  In  spite  of  the  vital  importance 
of  the  question  to  men  dependent  on  weekly  wages  for  their 
whole  livelihood,  no  Trade  Union  has  hitherto  devised  a 
regulation  which  secures  continuity  of  livelihood  as  a  con- 
dition of  employment. 

At  first  sight  it  would  seem  as  if  the  best  way  to  obtain 
Continuity  of  Employment  would  be  to  require  the  employer, 
as  a  condition  of  getting  the  workman's  service  at  all,  to 
enter  into  a  contract  of  hiring  for  a  specified  long  term. 
This  is  not  the  course  which  the  Trade  Unionists  have 
followed.  Engagements  for  long  terms  were  once  common 
in  many  trades,  and  farm-servants  in  some  parts  of  the 
country  are  still  engaged  for  the  year.  But  the  mobility 
and  vicissitudes  which  characterise  modern  industry  are 
hostile  to  such  permanence,  and  employers  have  come  to 
prefer  the  shortest  possible  engagements,  often  insisting  on 
freedom  to  discharge  their  operatives  at  a  few  hours'  notice. 
This  tendency,  far  from  being  resisted  by  the  Trade  Unions, 
has  invariably  been  encouraged  by  them.  The  Coalminers 
of  Northumberland  and  Durham  fought  hard  to  get  rid  of 
their  "yearly  bond";  the  Staffordshire  Potters  in  1866 
enthusiastically  threw  off  the  "  annual  hiring  "  ;  the  "  monthly 
pays,"  once  common  in  all  occupations,  have  been  replaced 
by  weekly,  or  at  most,  fortnightly  settlements  ;  and  many 
Trade  Unions  have,  at  one  time  or  another,  expressly  pro- 
hibited their  members  from  entering  into  longer  engagements, 
a  prohibition  now  generally  omitted  as  the  practice  has 
become  obsolete.2 

1  Preamble  to  Rules  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Tailors  (Manchester, 
1893). 

*  Thus  the  Scottish  Ironmoulders'  Society  has,  since  1838,  forbidden  engage- 


43 2  Trade  Union  Function 

This  policy  needs  no  explanation  for  any  one  who  under- 
stands the  Trade  Union  position.  The  "  yearly  bond  "  or 
annual  hiring  always  meant,  in  practice,  the  conclusion  of 
a  separate  agreement  between  the  employer  and  each  indi- 
vidual workman,  and  especially  when  the  various  terms  of 
service  did  not  expire  on  a  uniform  date,  was  incompatible 
with  Collective  Bargaining.  Moreover,  once  the  agreement 
was  entered  into,  the  wage-earner  found  himself,  at  any  rate 
for  the  specified  term  of  notice,  practically  at  the  mercy 
of  the  employer's  interpretation  of  the  conditions.  The 
wage  contract  seldom  contains  express  stipulations  with 
regard  to  any  other  points  than  the  amount  of  remuneration, 
and  perhaps  the  hours  of  labor,  and  it  is  always  implied 
that  the  wage-earner  binds  himself  to  obey  all  lawful  and 
reasonable  commands  of  his  "  master."  It  is  in  the  wage- 
earner's  power  to  throw  up  his  job  when  he  likes  that  his 
status  differs  most  essentially  from  that  of  a  slave,  and  if  he 
foregoes  this  power,  and  binds  himself  for  a  long  term  to 
put  up  with  practically  whatever  conditions,  outside  those 
expressly  stipulated  for,  the  employer  may  choose  to  impose, 
it  is  obvious  that  the  Trade  Union  loses  all  power  of  protect- 
ing him  against  economic  oppression.1  The  briefest  possible 
term  of  service,  terminable  at  a  day  or  a  week's  notice  on 
either  side,  has  accordingly  come  to  be  preferred,  for  different 
reasons,  by  both  employers  and  Trade  Unionists.2  This 

ments  longer  than  "from  pay  to  pay,"  the  rule  now  in  force  (1892)  providing 
"that  no  member  of  this  association  shall  enter  into  any  engagement,  either 
directly  or  indirectly,  for  any  given  time  longer  than  from  pay  to  pay,  unless 
specially  authorised  by  Executive."  The  United  Kingdom  Society  of  Coach- 
makers,  whose  rule  on  the  subject  dates  from  1840,  now  ordains  (1896  edition) 
that  "no  member  be  allowed  to  article  himself  under  penalty  of  expulsion." 
The  Tinplate  Workers  of  Glasgow  had  a  rule  in  1860  that  no  member  should  so 
engage  himself  as  to  prevent  his  leaving  his  employer  with  two  weeks'  notice ; 
the  Liverpool  Painters  said  one  week. — Report  on  Trade  Societies  and  Strikes^ 
by  the  Social  Science  Association  (London,  1860),  pp.  133,  297. 

1  We  recur  to  this  aspect  of  the  wage  contract  in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Higgling 
of  the  Market." 

2  It  was  a  special  aggravation  of  the  "yearly  bond"  among  the  Coalminers 
that,  whilst  the  workman  bound  himself  for  a  whole  year  to  hew  coal  whenever 
required   by  a  particular   employer,   that  employer  did  not  guarantee    to   find 
him  continuous  employment,  and  could   lay  the  pit  idle  whenever   he  chose 


Continuity  of  Employment  433 

does  not  mean,  as  regards  the  great  majority  of  industries, 
that  the  employers  are  incessantly  changing  their  workmen, 
or  workmen  their  employers.  Wherever  costly  and  intricate 
machinery  is  used,  and  wherever  the  processes  of  different 
workmen  are  dovetailed  one  into  the  other,  it  pays  the  em- 
ployer to  retain,  even  at  some  sacrifice,  the  services  of  the 
same  body  of  men,  accustomed  to  his  business  and  to  each 
other.  In  these  trades  accordingly,  a  well-conducted  work- 
man may  rely  on  retaining  his  employment  so  long  as  his 
employer  has  work  to  be  done. 

In  other  industries  this  absence  of  any  permanent  engage- 
ment between  master  and  man  leaves  the  employer  free  to 
get  his  work  done  to-day  by  one  set  of  workers,  and  to- 
morrow by  quite  another  set.  Whenever  work  is  "  given 
out "  to  be  done  in  the  workers'  own  homes,  the  employer 
can  dole  out  the  jobs  as  he  chooses,  sometimes  to  one 
family,  sometimes  to  another.  A  wholesale  clothing  con- 
tractor in  East  London  has  thus  hundreds  of  different 
families  looking  to  him  for  work,  amongst  whom  his  fore- 
man will,  each  week,  arbitrarily  apportion  his  orders.  The 
London  Dock  Companies  maintain  what  is  essentially  the 
same  system  with  regard  to  their  casual  labor,  the  fore- 
man, at  certain  periods  of  the  day,  selecting  fresh  gangs  of 
men  from  among  the  crowd  of  applicants  at  the  dock  gates. 
Both  outworkers  and  dockers  are  nominally  free  to  seek 
work  elsewhere,  when  not  engaged  by  their  usual  employer. 
But  as  they  are  expected,  under  pain  of  being  struck  off  the 
list,  to  present  themselves  to  ask  for  work  at  certain  hours, 
they  practically  lose  any  real  chance  of  obtaining  other 
employment.1  This  extreme  discontinuity  of  employment 

(R.  Fynes,  The  Miners  of  Northumberland  and  Durham,  Blyth,  1873).  A  similar 
one-sidedness  is  found  in  other  old  contracts  of  hiring.  The  chief  examples  of 
genuinely  bilateral  agreements  for  long  terms  relate  to  indoor  servants,  seamen, 
and  mechanics  sent  on  jobs  abroad. 

1  "The  Docks,"  by  Beatrice  Potter  (Mrs.  Sidney  Webb),  in  Charles  Booth's 
Life  and  Labor  of  the  People  (London,  1889),  vol.  i.  of  first  edition;  and 
H.  Llewellyn  Smith  and  Vaughan  Nash,  The  Story  of  the  Docker?  Strike 
(London,  1889).  This  system  of  engaging  casual  labor  by  the  hour  still  prevails 
in  the  London  docks,  but  it  has,  since  1890,  been  modified  by  an  increase  in  the 
VOL.  I  2  F 


434  Trade  Union  Function 

is  not  confined  to  unskilled  laborers  or  low  -  paid  home 
workers.  In  many  skilled  handicrafts,  where  the  work  is 
done  individually  and  by  the  piece,  the  operative  is  required 
to  remain  in  the  employer's  workshop,  or  at  his  beck  and 
call,  without  being  guaranteed  either  work  or  pay.  "  There 
are  firms,"  reported  to  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor 
the  representative  of  the  Sheffield  trades,  "  which  require 
their  workpeople  to  present  themselves  to  the  managers  to 
receive  work  at  certain  times  during  the  day.  When  they 
have  entered  the  place  in  the  morning  the  gates  are  closed, 
and  whether  they  have  work  or  not  they  cannot  leave  the 
premises  till  noon,  except  by  special  permit  from  the  firm, 
and  so  from  noon  to  evening.  ...  I  know  of  a  case  in  the 
steel  trade  where  the  men  were  expected  to  be  in  the  firm 
from  9  A.M.  to  6  P.M.,  if  they  had  but  five  shillings'  worth  of 
work  during  the  week.  The  men  struck  against  it."  l  The 
Macclesfield  Silk -weavers  are  in  an  even  worse  position. 
The  employers  "  give  out "  work  to  be  done  in  the  weavers' 
own  homes,  and  distribute  it  so  irregularly  that  a  workman 
may  be  kept  idle  for  days  or  even  weeks.  Nevertheless,  as 
the  handloom  belongs  to  the  employer,  the  operative  has  to 
pay  loom-rent  for  it  week  by  week  with  absolute  continuity, 
whether  any  work  has  been  given  to  him  or  not,  and  he  is 
forbidden  by  the  owner  of  the  loom  to  use  it  for  any  other 
manufacturer  who  might  offer  work. 

To  capitalists  concerned  only  for  present  profit,  this 
extreme  discontinuity  of  employment  offers  several  ad- 
number  of  men  who  are  given  preferences  for  employment.  The  dockers 
now  divided  into  three  registered  classes  (permanent  men,  A  list,  and  13  list,  e 
man  being  numbered  in  his  own  class),  and  one  unregistered  class  (C  or  casuals). 
No  guarantee  of  employment  is  given  to  any  man,  but  each  day's  work  is  allotted, 
as  far  as  it  will  go,  strictly  according  to  the  order  of  the  classes  and  the  numeric 
order  of  the  men  in  each  class.  Thus,  the  regularity  of  employment  of  tl 
preference  men  has  been  increased  at  the  expense  of  making  the  work  of  tl 
casual  docker  less  continuous  than  before.  In  so  far  as  the  change  is  a  stej 
towards  the  total  abolition  of  the  casual  system,  it  must  be  regarded  as 
improvement. — See  Charles  Booth,  Life  and  Labor  of  the  People,  vol.  vii. 
(London,  1896);  and  the  chapter  on  "  Les  Unions  de  Dockers"  in  Le  Trac 
Unionism  en  Angleferre,  edited  by  Paul  de  Rousiers  (Paris,  1897). 

1  Evidence  of  C.  Hobson,  Q.  19,029,  before  Royal  Commission  on  Labor 
(Group  A),  24th  March  1892. 


Continuity  of  Employment  435 

vantages.  Where  the  industry  is  seasonal  or  otherwise 
irregular  in  volume,  as  in  the  case  of  dock  labor  and  the 
clothing  trade,  the  employer  is  able,  without  expense  to 
himself,  to  expand  or  contract  his  working  staff  in  exact 
proportion  to  the  state  of  the  weather  or  change  of  tides  or 
seasons.  The  giver-out  of  work  can  at  any  moment  quad- 
ruple his  production  to  fulfil  a  pressing  order,  and  then  drop 
back  to  the  current  demands  of  a  slack  season,  without 
incurring  factory-rent  or  other  standing  charges.  The  army 
of  men  and  women  standing  at  his  beck  and  call  cost  him 
nothing  except  for  the  actual  hours  that  they  are  at  work. 
And  the  very  existence  of  such  a  "  reserve  army "  places 
each  member  of  it  more  completely  at  his  mercy  with  regard 
to  all  the  conditions  of  employment.  Wherever  this  "  reserve 
army "  exists  in  conjunction  with  home-work,  or  otherwise 
under  circumstances  making  Individual  Bargaining  inevitable, 
the  employer  can  practically  dictate  terms.  How  disas- 
trously the  whole  arrangement  operates  for  the  workers  con- 
cerned has  been  described  by  every  observer  of  the  sweated 
trades. 

To  oppose  such  a  disastrous  irregularity  of  work  is  a 
fundamental  principle  of  Trade  Unionism.  Unfortunately, 
where  the  system  prevails,  the  workers  are  seldom  in  a 
position  to  combine  for  their  own  protection.  We  see  a 
feeble  attempt  to  cope  with  the  evil  in  the  regulation  of 
the  Dock,  Wharf,  and  Riverside  Laborers'  Union,  that  any 
man  taken  on  in  the  London  docks  shall  be  guaranteed  at 
least  four  hours'  continuous  work.  Certain  classes  of  rail- 
way servants  complain  that,  whilst  they  are  forbidden  by  the 
railway  company  to  take  any  other  employment,  they  are 
given  only  casual  and  intermittent  work,  and  paid  only  by 
the  job.  To  remedy  this  grievance  the  General  Railway 
Workers'  Union  is  proposing  that  it  should  be  enacted  by 
law  that  every  person  who  is  required  "to  give  the  whole  of 
his  time  to  the  service  of  the  company  shall,  unless  legally 
dismissed  from  such  service,  before  his  employment  is  termi- 
nated, be  entitled  to  a  week's  notice,  or  a  week's  wages  in  lieu 


43 ^  Trade  Union  Function 

of  notice,  and  he  shall  be  entitled  to  full  weekly  wages 
while  in  such  employment."  ]  But  examples  of  Trade  Union 
policy  on  this  point  must  be  sought  in  the  more  strongly 
organised  trades  in  which,  though  so  dangerous  a  discon- 
tinuity does  not  actually  exist,  there  is  some  danger  that 
it  might,  if  not  resisted,  insidiously  creep  in.  Thus,  the 
highly-paid  compositors  in  London  daily  newspaper  offices 
who  must  stand  by  waiting  for  copy  to  come  in,  and  then 
work  at  lightning  speed  to  catch  the  press,  insist  on  all 
the  men  in  attendance  being  guaranteed  "  a  galley  and 
a  half" — that  is,  being  paid  53.  gd.  on  a  morning  paper, 
or  55.  4  |-d.  on  an  evening  paper — whether  they  are  actu- 
ally required  to  do  as  much  work  or  not.2  The  old- 
fashioned  union  of  hand-working  Papermakers  goes  farther, 
and  rigidly  enforces  the  Regulation  known  as  the  "  Six 
Days'  Custom,"  which  ensures  that  not  less  than  six  days' 
work,  or  the  equivalent  payment,  shall  be  found  each  week 
for  all  the  men  employed.  If  an  accident  occurs,  or  an 
engine  breaks  down,  the  employer  no  more  thinks  of 
depriving  his  workmen  of  their  livelihood  during  the  stoppage 
than  he  does  that  of  his  clerks  or  manager.  He  can  dis- 
charge his  men  by  giving  them  the  customary  fortnight's 
notice,  or  by  paying  them  the  customary  forfeit  of  one 
guinea,  but  so  long  as  he  retains  their  services  he  must  pay 
them  at  least  the  agreed  minimum  of  weekly  wages.3 

1  General  Secretary's  Report  to  Annual  General  Meeting  1897. 

2  The  minimum  used  to  be  "one  galley";  then  the  rule  ran,  in  mystic 
phrase,  "one  galley  four  hours'  work,  and  extra  pay  for  more  than  a  quarter 
galley  an  hour  when  asked  to  pull  out."    We  are  indebted  to  Mr.  C.  Drummond 
for  the  following  explanation.     The  newspaper  compositors,  being  paid  by  the 
piece,  and  guaranteed  a  minimum  of  work,  can  do  it  at  their  own  speed.     But  in 
order  that  the  "printer"  (i.e.  manager  of  the  department)  may  have  some  control 
over  the  time  taken,  it  is  agreed  that  the  maximum  within  which  one  galley  must 
be  completed  is  four  hours,  though  the  compositor  will,  for  his  own  sake,  seldom 
take  so  long.     It  happens  very  occasionally,  when  the  "  printer  "  is  compelled  to 
insist  on  the  utmost  possible  speed,  that  he  will  order  the  men  to  "pull  out,"  i.e. 
use  every  effort.     Men  working  under  such  an  order  are  entitled  to  extra  pay 
for  all  over  a  quarter  of  a  galley  done  in  an  hour. 

3  "  That  the  Six  Days'  Custom  be  as  follows :  Twenty-two  post  per  day  and 
ten  on  Saturday"  (Rules  and  Regulations  of  the  Original  Society  of  Papermakers  > 
Maidstone,  1887),  Rule  28.     The  French  paper-makers  in  the  eighteenth  century 


Continuity  of  Employment  437 

Similarly,  the  Flint  Glass  Makers  have  a  binding  custom  by 
which  the  employer  is  required  to  find  his  men  a  minimum 
of  "  eleven  moves  a  week,"  being  thirty-three  hours'  work,  or 
pay  a  corresponding  amount  in  wages.1 

In  other  trades  where  work  is  irregular,  the  Trade 
Union  objection  to  its  being  arbitrarily  distributed  by  the 
employer — leading,  as  this  does,  to  the  extreme  dependence 
of  the  wage-earner — has  led  to  regulations  for  "sharing 
work."  If  the  workmen  know  that,  however  scanty  may  be 
the  work  to  be  done,  it  will  be  fairly  distributed  among  them 
all,  there  is  much  less  temptation  for  the  poorer  or  more 
grasping  members  to  seek  to  secure  themselves  by  offering 
to  accept  worse  conditions  of  employment.2 

The  most  primitive  form  of  sharing  work  is  seen  in  the 
'  turnway  "  societies  of  the  Thames  watermen,  for  regulating 
the  "  turns,"  or  order  in  which  the  men  plying  at  any 
particular  "  stairs "  serve  the  passengers  who  present  them- 
selves.3 What  is  essentially  the  same  arrangement  is 
presented  by  the  "  House  of  Call "  system,  under  which, 
among  the  Tailors,  Compositors,  Bakers,  Upholsterers,  and 
sometimes  Joiners  and  Painters,  the  employer  wanting  a 

required  six  weeks'  notice  on  either  side. — Du  Cellier,  Histoire  des  Classes 
Laborieuses  en  France  (Paris,  1860),  p.  292. 

1  This  custom  is  recognised  in  the  trade,  and  is  enforced  by  County  Court 
judges,  if  the  wage  contract  includes  no  express  stipulation  to  the  contrary.     See 
the  cases  reported  in  the  Flint  Glass  Maker?  Magazine,  August  1874  and  March 
1875*  m  the  Birmingham  and  Rotherham  County  Courts. 

2  The  growth  of  the  great  industry  and  the  world  commerce  led  to  a  similar 
development  in   French   Trade    Unionism.       Du    Cellier    (Histoire  des    Classes 
Laborieuses  en  France,  p.  385)  notes  that,  after  1830,  the  workmen's  associations 
were  occupied  in  devising  means  to  mitigate  the  evils  of  unemployment.     Where 
the  work  was  individual  in  character,  the  employer  was  obliged  to  give  the  jobs 
in  succession  to  the  several  workmen  in  their  order  on  the  roll.     "Where  the  work 
was  done  in  concert,  it  was  shared  equally  by  the  whole  staff,  instead  of  the 
number  being  reduced. 

3  These  "turnway  societies,"   incidentally  described   in   Mayhew's  London 
Labour  and  the  London  Poor  (London,    1851),  are  probably  of  great  antiquity. 
There  were  societies  of  watermen  at  Rotherhithe  in  1789,  and  of  those  "usually 
plying  at  the  Hermitage  Stairs"  in  1799,  whilst  already  in  1669  we  read  that 
"our  Gravesend  watermen,  by  some  temporary  and  mean  pretences  of  the  late 
Dutch  war,  have  raised  their  ferry  double  to  what  it  was,  and  finding  the  sweet 
thereof,  keep  it  up  still "  (Thomas  Manley's  Usury  at  Six  per  Cent  Examined, 
London,  1669).      See  the  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  ir,  20. 


43 8  Trade  Union  Function 

workman  is  encouraged  or  required  to  send  to  a  place  of 
resort  for  the  unemployed,  and  the  man  who  has  been  longest 
on  the  list  is,  if  suitable,  deputed  to  fill  the  vacancy.1  This 
arrangement,  which  is  in  some  trades  worked  for  the  mutual 
convenience  of  both  parties,  may  degenerate  into  a  refusal 
to  the  employer  of  any  power  of  selection.  Thus  the  Flint 
Glass  Makers  insist  on  the  employer  taking  the  member  who 
has  been  the  longest  out  of  work,2  whether  he  is  competent, 
or  suitable,  or  not ;  and  the  Silk  Hatters  expressly  arrange 
so  that  the  employer  may  not  even  see  the  man  assigned  to 
him,  before  he  is  engaged.3  This  is,  in  effect,  to  maintain 
a  craft  monopoly,  having  all  the  economic  characteristics  of 

1  The  Compositors  at  London,  Glasgow,   Manchester,  etc.,  use  the  Trade 
Union  Office  for  this  purpose ;  and  the  Engineers  at  Manchester  keep  a  "vacant 
book "  in  their  local  office.     Most  of  the  smaller  trades  use  particular  public- 
houses  as  their  "  House  of  Call,"  the  publican  often  himself  keeping  the  register 
of  the  unemployed.     For  incidental  descriptions  of  the  "  House  of  Call"  system, 
see  The  Tailoring  Trade,  by  F.  W.  Gallon. 

In  France  the  practice  of  sharing  employment  was  carried  so  far  in  some 
of  the  incorporated  handicrafts  that  the  member  who  had  been  longest  in 
continuous  work  ceded  his  place  in  favor  of  any  who  had  remained  a  certain 
time  unemployed. — Du  Cellier,  Histoire  des  Classes  Laborieuses  en  France,  p.  289. 

2  Rules  and  Regulations  of  the  National  Flint  Glass  Makers  Sick  and  Friendly 
Society  (Manchester,  1891).      Rule  X.  is  as  follows:    "When  a  man  falls  out 
of  employment  the  F[actory]  Secretary]  shall  inform  the  District]  Secretary] 
who  shall  at  once  write  to  the  C[entral]  Secretary]  for  an  unemployed  certificate  ; 
and  when  a  man  is  applied  for  by  an  employer  the  F.S.  shall  apply  to  the 
D.S.,  and  should  there  be  no  one  suitable  in  the  district,  he  shall  write  to 
the  C.S.  stating  what  kind  of  man  is  wanted,  wages,  etc.,  so  that  there  be  no 
mistake  as  to  the  man  sent  to  fill  the  situation.      When  an  employer  applies  for 
men  the  unemployed  roll  shall  be  consulted  before  any  promotions  be  granted 
either  to  journeymen  or  apprentices.     Note. — Rule  X.  is  not  intended  to  compel 
a  master  to  engage  any  man  to  whom  he  has  a  reasonable  objection,  the  same 
to  be  considered  by  the  District  Committee."      The  Flint  Glass  Makers*  Magazine 
contains  many  references  to  employers'  complaints  of  this  procedure. 

3  The  Silk  Hatters'  custom  is  so  universal  that  it  is  only  incidentally  referred 
to  in  the  rules.     As  explained  to  us  by  officers  of  the  union  it  is  as  follows  : 
"  Employers  are  not  allowed  to  choose,  or  even  to  see,  workmen  whom  they 
engage.     A  member  out  of  work  calls  at  a  hatter's  workshop,  and  sends  in  a 
small  card  (the  'asking  ticket'),  showing  that  he  is  a  financial  member  (i.e.  not 
in  arrear  with  his  contribution),   and  what  branch    of  work   he   does.      The 
journeymen  in  each  workshop  take  it  in  turns  to  attend  to  such  cards.     On  its 
being  sent  in,  the  man  whose  turn  it  is  goes  in  to  the  employer  and  asks,  '  Do  you 
want  a  bodymaker  ? '  (or  a  shaper,  as  the  case  may  be).     This  is  called  '  asking 
for'  the  unemployed  member.      If  the  employer  says  'yes,'  the  man  is  told  to 
come  in  and  commence.     If  '  no,'  his  card  is  returned,  and  he  goes  off  to  the 
next  shop." 


Continuity  of  Employment  439 

a  drastic  restriction  of  numbers,  with  which  it  is  invariably 
combined.1 

Any  such  restriction  on  the  employer's  freedom  of  choice 
between  one  workman  and  another  is,  however,  quite 
exceptional.  More  generally,  the  Trade  Union  seeks  to 
promote  the  sharing  of  work  by  regulations  directed  against 
the  greed  or  selfishness  of  its  own  members.  Thus  the  Ship- 
wrights' Provident  Union  of  the  Port  of  London  retains  to  the 
present  day  the  substance  of  its  original  rule  of  1824  that  "  no 
member  shall  engross  a  greater  quantity  of  work  than  he  can 
accomplish  by  working  the  regular  hours  of  the  trade,  viz. 
not  before  or  after  the  recognised  working  hours  per  day 
throughout  the  year ;  and  that  no  work  be  performed  inside 
after  the  men  on  the  outside  of  the  ship  have  left  work,  so 
that  every  opportunity  may  be  given  to  those  who  are  out 
of  employ." 2  The  same  intention  inspires  the  regulations 
in  many  handwork  trades  against  "  smooting  "  or  "  foxing  " 
or  "  grassing,"  that  is,  working  for  a  second  employer  after 
putting  in  a  full  day  elsewhere.  Thus  the  Manchester 
Union  of  Saddlers  provides  that  "  no  member  of  this  union 
shall  be  allowed  habitually  to  work  for  any  other  employer 
than  the  one  by  whom  he  is  regularly  employed,  except 
there  are  none  out  of  work  in  the  branch.  And  no  member 
shall  be  allowed  to  obtain  any  work  at  this  trade  whilst  in  a 
situation,  to  do  after  his  working  hours  for  any  person  except 
his  own  employer." 3  And  the  Wool  Shear  Benders  and 
Grinders,  a  tiny  Sheffield  handicraft,  absolutely  prohibit 
their  members  from  working  in  any  other  wheel  or  factory 
than  the  one  in  which  they  are  regularly  employed.4  An 

1  We  recur  to  this  subject  in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Economic  Characteristics  of 
Trade  Unionism." 

2  Rules  of  the  Shipwrights'  Provident  Union  of  the  Port  of  London ;  see 
ihe  original  wording  in  a  note  to  the  chapter  on  "The  Normal  Day." 

3  Rules  of  the  Union  of  the  Saddler S,  Harness  Makers,  etc.  (Manchester,  1889). 
Similar  rules  exist  in  many  other  trades,  such  as  the  Compositors,  Brushmakers, 
Coachmakers,  etc. 

4  The  Yorkshire  Glass  Bottle  Makers'  Society  lias  a  signed  agreement  with  all 
the  employers,  which  is  renewed  annually.    Among  other  matters,  it  provides  that 
"in  the  event  of  any  furnace  being  out  for  repairs,  slack  trade,  or  stopped  for 


440  Trade  Union  Function 

extreme  case  is  presented  by  the  Scythe  Grinders'  Trade 
Protection  Society,  which  arranges  for  its  members  a  definite 
year's  engagement,  in  all  cases  terminating  on  the  6th  of  July 
(Old  Midsummer  Day),  by  which  it  is  understood  that  no 
man  is  ever  discharged  during  the  year  for  slackness  of  trade, 
the  ebbs  and  flows  of  the  work  of  each  establishment  being 
shared  among  the  staff  with  which  it  started  the  year.  But 
these  are  archaic  survivals.  In  the  great  modern  unions 
any  desire  to  promote  the  sharing  of  work  by  regulations  of 
this  type  is  merged  in  the  general  objection  to  Overtime, 
and  the  maintenance  of  the  Normal  Day. 

The  common  Trade  Union  desire  to  maintain  the  Normal 
Day,  especially  in  its  manifestations  against  Overtime  and  in 
favor  of  a  Reduction  of  the  Hours  of  Labor,  has  at  all  times 
been  strengthened  by  the  belief  that  a  strict  regulation  of  the 
working  time  would  incidentally  cause  employment  to  be 
more  continuous.  Thus,  the  Amalgamated  Association  of 
Operative  Cotton-spinners,  in  supporting  Lord  Shaftesbury's 
u  Ten  Hours'  Bill,"  gave  as  one  of  their  objects,  "  a  more 
equitable  adjustment  or  distribution  of  labor,  by  means  of 
shortening  the  hours  of  labor."1  And  when,  in  1872,  there 
was  a  new  movement  for  reducing  the  Normal  Day,  the 
same  idea  recurs  in  the  argument  that  this  would  "  secure 

any  other  cause,  the  workmen  shall,  as  far  as  practicable,  share  the  work ;  provided, 
nevertheless,  that  if  after  a  furnace  has  been  out  for  four  months,  and  there  is  no 
probability  of  its  being  started  again,  the  master  to  be  at  liberty  to  discharge  the 
surplus  workmen." 

1  Circular  of  iQth  January  1845,  in  Minute  Book.  Fifteen  years  later  the 
Cotton-spinners  thus  referred  to  their  successful  agitation  :  "It  should  always 
be  remembered  that  anterior  to  the  introduction  of  factory  legislation,  the  em- 
ployers dictated  the  hours  of  labor  to  their  workpeople ;  and  in  the  various 
localities  those  hours  varied  accordingly,  ranging  from  seventy-four  hours  and 
upwards.  As,  however,  in  some  instances  the  mills  were  kept  running  night 
and  day,  we  shall  certainly  be  under  the  mark  in  assuming  that  the  average 
hours  worked  at  that  time,  throughout  the  country,  were  75  per  cent  per  week. 
It  is  obvious  that  sixty  people  working  seventy-five  hours  per  week  would  produce 
nearly  as  much  as  seventy-five  now  do  working  sixty  hours,  and  thus  from  20  to  25 
per  cent  of  the  factory  population  would  be  thrown  destitute  upon  the  streets.  It 
is  equally  clear,  moreover,  that  it  is  the  scarcity  or  redundance  of  labor  in  the 
market  which  regulates  the  rate  of  wages ;  and,  as  under  the  circumstances  we 
have  named,  some  of  the  workpeople  would  be  almost  worked  to  death,  while 
those  thrown  out  would  be  reduced  to  a  state  bordering  on  starvation  from  the 


Continuity  of  Employment  441 

them  moderate  but  constant  employment."1  In  so  far  as 
this  means  only  that  a  reduction  of  the  hours  of  those  in 
employment  would,  other  things  being  equal,  cause  the  work 
to  be  shared  among  a  larger  number  of  operatives,  and  so 
prevent  some  from  being  wholly  unemployed,  the  case  is, 
like  that  of  the  Shipwrights  whose  rule  we  have  quoted, 
merely  one  of  sharing  work.  As  unemployed  men  have  to 
be  maintained  somehow,  generally  by  their  fellow-members, 
it  may  well  be  more  convenient  to  the  whole  body  that  the 
largest  possible  number  should  be  employed  for  the  normal 
hours,  than  that  some  should  be  working  abnormally  long 
days,  and  others  walking  the  streets  in  search  of  a  job.  In 
times  of  general  depression  of  trade,  or  of  temporary  contrac- 
tion of  demand  for  a  particular  industry,  such  an  arrange- 
ment seems  to  the  Trade  Unionist  obviously  reasonable. 
The  employer,  on  the  other  hand,  more  than  usually  eager 
in  bad  times  to  reduce  the  cost  of  production,  would  prefer 
to  lengthen  the  hours  of  labor,  so  as  (at  time  wages)  to  get 
more  work  for  the  same  weekly  wage,  or  (at  piece  rates)  to 
get  a  larger  output  in  proportion  to  his  standing  charges. 
Hence  we  arrive  at  the  paradox  that  it  is  generally  in  times 
of  depression,  when  the  world  requires  less  carpentering  or 
engineering  work  to  be  done,  that  attempts  are  made  to 
lengthen  the  Normal  Day  of  those  carpenters  and  engineers 
who  are  in  employment  at  all,  with  the  result  that  the 
number  out  of  employment  is  unnecessarily  increased.  In 
1879,  f°r  instance,  at  a  time  of  exceptional  contraction  of 

want  of  it,  the  wages  of  labor  would,  as  a  matter  of  course,  from  the  intense 
competition  to  obtain  employment,  come  down  to  starvation  point ;  and  all  our 
efforts,  whether  exerted  singly  or  in  concert,  would  be  utterly  powerless  to  arrest 
their  downward  course.  It  is  clearly  then  the  duty  and  interest  of  every  worker 
in  the  factories  of  this  country  to  resist,  by  every  legitimate  means  in  his  power, 
not  only  any  attempt  to  violate  the  law  by  overworking  women,  young  persons, 
and  children,  but  to  treat  with  contempt  all  overtures  by  which  it  is  sought  to 
induce  him  to  work  more  than  sixty  hours  per  week,  inasmuch  as  this  righteous 
law  is  the  palladium  of  his  success  in  his  endeavour  to  improve  his  social  con- 
dition."—  Rules  of  the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners, 
edition  of  1860,  preface. 

1  Circular  of  7th  January  1872,  ibid.     See,  for  other  examples,  The  Eight 
Hoiin,'  Day,  by  Sidney  Webb  and  Harold  Cox  (London,  1891). 


44  2  Trade  Union  Function 

business,  the  Clyde  shipbuilders  insisted  on  increasing  the 
working  hours  from  fifty-one  to  fifty-four  per  week,  and  the 
Manchester  builders  added  from  two  to  three  hours  to  the 
working  week.1  It  is  in  face  of  attempts  of  this  sort  that 
the  Trade  Union  Regulations  for  maintaining  the  Normal 
Day  seem  incidentally  to  protect  the  workers  from  an 
unnecessary  discontinuity  of  employment. 

The  reader  will  see  on  closer  examination  that  these 
Regulations,  though  apparently  directed  towards  Continuity 
of  Employment,  are  in  reality  designed  primarily  to  prevent 
the  evils  of  Individual  Bargaining,  and  to  save  the  workmen, 
especially  in  bad  times,  from  falling  into  personal  dependence 
on  the  employer  or  his  foreman.  Thus  the  Trade  Union 
objection  to  the  conditions  of  employment  being  fixed  in 
advance  for  long  periods  completely  disappears,  as  we  may 
learn  from  the  little  example  of  the  Scythe-grinders,  when 
this  fixing  takes  place  by  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining. 
The  "  Working  Rules,"  for  which  all  sections  of  the  building 
trade  persistently  struggle,  habitually  determine  the  rates  of 
wages,  hours  of  labor,  and  many  other  conditions  for  an 
indefinitely  long  period,  from  which  neither  employers  nor 
workmen  can  depart  without  giving  six  months'  notice.  The 
Miners'  Federation  in  1893  willingly  bound  themselves  to 
continue  to  accept  the  then  existing  rates  of  wages  for  a 
year,  in  return  for  a  corresponding  pledge  from  the  associated 
employers  not  to  seek  a  reduction  during  that  period.  In 
like  manner,  the  Trade  Union  objection  to  the  doling  out  of 
work  in  slack  seasons  ceases  when  this  distribution  is  made 
in  accordance  with  any  such  collective  arrangement  among 
the  operatives  themselves  as  those  that  we  have  just  de- 
scribed.2 None  of  these  regulations  secures^  or  even  attempts 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  332-334. 

2  The  workers  may  even  resort  to  the  primitive  expedient  of  casting  lots ; 
thus  the  Rules  and  Regulations  of  the  Warpers'  True  Benevolent  Sick  and  Burial 
Society  (Rochdale,  1884)  prescribe  "that  when  a  mill  stops  working  where  our 
members  are  employed,  and  it  is  obvious  that  such  stoppage  will  be  for  some 
time,  when  all  the  men  are  finishing  their  work  within  two  days,  they  shall  cast 
lots  whose  name  shall  be  first  on  the  list." 


Continuity  of  Employment  443 

to  secure,  to  the  workmen  a  full  week's  work  or  a  full  week's 
wage  for  every  week  in  the  year.  They  have  little  real  bear- 
ing on  Continuity  of  Employment  and  are,  in  substance, 
only  incidents  of  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining,  re- 
quired to  maintain  the  Standard  Rate  and  the  Normal  Day. 

There  are,  in  fact,  no  Trade  Union  Regulations  placing 
upon  the  employer  the  obligation  of  providing  continuous 
employment  for  the  wage -earners  whom  he  chooses  to 
engage.  Wisely  or  unwisely  the  Trade  Unions  have  tacitly 
accepted  the  position  that  the  capitalist  can  only  be  ex- 
pected to  find  them  wages  so  long  as  he  can  find  them 
work.  Continuity  of  employment  becomes,  therefore,  con- 
tingent upon  continuity  of  the  consumer's  demand,  or  more 
precisely,  upon  an  exact  adjustment  of  Supply  and  Demand. 
Both  employers  and  workmen  wish  this  adjustment  made  and 
continuity  secured.  But  capitalists  and  manual  workers  have, 
with  a  few  exceptions  on  both  sides,  advocated  diametrically 
opposite  ways  of  obtaining  it.  When  business  becomes  slack 
and  sales  fall  off,  the  employer's  first  instinct  is  to  tempt 
customers  by  lowering  prices.  He  assumes  that,  whatever 
may  be  the  cause  of  the  depression,  he  can  still  get  orders,  and 
so  keep  his  mills  going  full  time,  if  only  he  is  enabled  to  quote 
a  sufficiently  low  price  for  his  product.  For  this  reduction 
he  looks  mainly  to  the  rate  of  wages.  The  landlord  insists 
on  his  fixed  rent  or  royalty,  and  the  mortgagee  or  debenture 
holder  on  his  fixed  interest.  It  would  be  fatal  to  economise 
on  buildings,  machinery,  or  plant,  which  must  either  be  kept 
up  to  their  highest  efficiency  or  replaced  earlier  than  need 
be  at  serious  cost  to  himself.  It  is  not  worth  while,  and  it 
is  contrary  to  the  brainworker's  tradition,  to  nibble  at  the 
salaries  of  managers  or  clerks.  The  conclusion  seems 
inevitable.  The  alternative  to  stopping  altogether  is,  whilst 
the  employer  temporarily  foregoes  some  of  his  profits,  the 
workman  shall  forego  some  of  his  wages. 

The  Trade    Unionists  entirely  dissent  from  this  policy.1 

1  Thus,  the   factory  bootmakers,   in   a   time  of  great  depression  of  trade, 
emphatically  protested  against  the  employers'  policy      "When  in  consequence 


444  Trade  Union  Function 

They  point  out  that,  to  them,  it  is  not  a  question  of  tem- 
porarily diminishing  surplus  profits  ;  what  is  at  stake  is  their 
weekly  livelihood,  the  actual  housekeeping  of  their  families 
and  themselves.  To  the  vast  majority  of  workmen,  a  ten 
per  cent  reduction  of  wages  means  an  actual  diminution  of 
food  and  warmth,  an  actual  privation  in  the  way  of  clothing 
and  house-accommodation,  which  they  declare  to  be  physi- 
cally exhausting  and  detrimental  to  their  industrial  efficiency. 
No  manufacturer  would  think  it  wise  to  let  his  buildings  and 
machinery  fall  into  disrepair,  or  to  reduce  the  ration  and 
stable  accommodation  of  his  horses  ;  why,  asks  the  Trade 
Unionist,  should  he  adopt  this  suicidal  policy  with  regard  to 
the  most  important  factors  of  his  productive  efficiency, — the 
human  laborers  whom  he  employs  ?  1  If  the  employer,  under 
the  pressure  of  competition  in  slack  times,  tempts  the  con- 
sumer to  buy  his  particular  commodity  by  indefinitely 
worsening  the  conditions  of  employment,  he  is,  in  thus 
deteriorating  the  physique  and  character  of  successive  relays 
of  workers,  giving  away  what  does  not  belong  to  him,  the 
capital  value  of  the  human  beings  in  his  service. 

It  is  a  further  aggravation  to  the  Trade  Unionist  that 
he  believes  the  sacrifice  demanded  of  him  by  the  employer 
to  be  worse  than  useless.  Merely  to  offer  commodities  at  a 
lower  price  in  no  way  increases  the  world's  aggregate  demand 

of  the  reckless  unscrupulous  competition  among  capitalists  we  find  our  com- 
merce becoming  less  day  by  day,  banks  stopping  payment,  firms  which  had 
become  bywords  in  the  past  for  their  supposed  stability  found  to  be  in  a  state  of 
hopeless  insolvency,  we  protest  against  that  doctrine  which  would  find  a  panacea 
for  these  evils  in  a  general  reduction  of  the  wages  of  the  workers  or  an  increase 
in  their  hours  of  labor." — Monthly  Report  of  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and 
Shoe  Operatives  (December  1879). 

1  The  acceptance  by  employers  of  contracts  at  prices  which  cannot  possibly 
be  made  to  pay  at  the  existing  rates  of  wages  is  a  subject  of  constant  complaint. 
The  preface  to  the  Bylaws,  Order  of  Business,  and  Rules  of  Order  of  the  Window  - 
Glass  Workers  of  England  (Sunderland,  1886)  declares,  "Whilst  admitting  that 
sometimes  pressure  is  brought  to  bear  on  the  capitalists  or  employers,  [that] 
in  too  many  instances,  instead  of  offering  any  resistance,  they  accept  terms  that 
are  disadvantageous  to  themselves,  trusting  to  their  power  of  remunerating 
themselves  by  legally  pilfering  a  portion  off  each  of  their  workers'  weekly 
earnings ;  and  there  is  no  limit  to  the  extremes  to  which  labor  can  be  pushed, 
unless  it  be  that  fixed  by  the  Poor-Law  authorities  and  the  price  paid  for  their 
test  labor." 


Continuity  of  Employment  445 

for  commodities.  It  may  suit  the  immediate  purposes  of  a 
single  employer,  by  undercutting  his  rivals,  to  engross  their 
trade.  It  might  conceivably  suit  all  the  employers  in  a 
particular  trade,  by  cheapening  their  wares,  to  engross  more 
of  the  aggregate  demand  for  commodities  than  would  other- 
wise come  their  way.1  But  in  either  case  the  total  demand 
remains  the  same,  being,  in  fact,  identical  with  the  total 
product,  and  all  that  has  happened  is  a  gain  in  continuity 
in  one  direction,  balanced  by  an  equivalent  loss  somewhere 
else  Thus,  the  Trade  Unionist  declares  a  lowering  of  price 
to  be  no  real  cure  for  a  general  depression  of  trade.  When 
such  a  policy  is  adopted  all  round,  the  aggregate  income  of 
the  producers  is  no  greater  than  it  would  have  been  if  they 
had  kept  up  their  rates  and  done  less  work.  The  only 
result  is  that  the  workers  have  to  do  more  work  for  the  same 
money,  and  though  the  wage-earners  share,  as  consumers,  in 
the  benefit  of  the  lowered  prices,  the  fact  that  they  only 
consume  a  third  of  the  product  makes  the  operation  a  net 
loss  to  their  class.2  If  it  is  retorted  that  one  country  may, 
by  a  judicious  cheapening  of  its  products,  engross  more  than 
its  normal  share  of  the  diminished  trade  of  the  world,  and 
so  keep  its  own  wage -earners  employed  at  the  cost  of 

1  It  must  not  be  forgotten  that  a  fall  in  the  wages  of  any  particular  section  of 
workers  would,  at  best,  produce  a  much  less  than  proportionate  fall  in  the  retail 
price  of  their  product.     Thus,  when  the  Northumberland  coal  hewers  are  urged 
to  submit  to  a  ten  per  cent  reduction,  in  order  to  stimulate  the  demand  for  their 
coal,  they  may  well  reply  that,  receiving  as  they  do  on  an  average  about  I5d.  per 
ton  of  coal  hewn,  this  ten  per  cent  reduction  of  wages,  which  would  mean  a 
serious  shrinking  of  their  family  incomes,  could  not  possibly  result  in  lowering  the 
price  to  the  London  consumer  to  a  greater  degree  than  from  245.  to  235.  io£d. 
per  ton,  or  by  about  a  half  per  cent. 

The  actual  variations  of  price  have,  in  most  industries,  little  connection  with 
variations  of  wages.  "  During  the  last  twenty  years  the  retail  price  of  cotton 
thread  has  varied  from  a  penny  to  twopence  per  spool  of  200  yards — that  is,  loo 
per  cent — following,  more  or  less  closely,  the  variations  of  manufacturers'  prices. 
All  this  time  the  wages  of  women  workers,  who  constitute  the  great  majority  of 
operatives  in  the  thread  mills,  have  scarcely  varied." — Prof.  W.  Smart,  Studies  in 
Economics  (London,  1896),  p.  259. 

2  In  the  United  Kingdom  from  three-fifths  to  two-thirds  of  the  annual  pro- 
duct of  commodities  and  services  are  consumed  by  the  one-fifth  of  the  population 
above  the  wage-earning  class ;  see  the  reference  to  official  statistics  given  in  Facts 
for  Socialists  (Fabian  Tract,  No.  5). 


446  Trade  Union  Function 

foreigners,  the  Trade  Unionist  has  the  reply  that,  according 
to  the  orthodox  Theory  of  International  Trade,  any  such 
artificial  stimulus  to  national  industry  must  necessarily  be 
as  powerless  to  increase  the  total  volume  of  the  trade  as 
a  Protective  Tariff  or  a  system  of  Bounties  on  Exports. 
We  shall  examine  the  whole  of  this  argument  in  our  chapter 
on  "  The  Economic  Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism."  It 
concerns  us  here  only  as  explaining  the  persistent  Trade 
Union  policy  of  fighting  their  hardest  against  any  lowering 
of  wages,  and  submitting  only  to  superior  force.1 

But  certain  sections  of  the  Trade  Union  world  do  not 
stop  at  this  negative  attitude.  They  have  propounded,  as 
a  means  of  coping  with  depression  of  trade,  a  diametrically 
opposite  policy,  which  they  have  done  their  best  to  press 
their  employers  to  adopt.  The  Cotton  Operatives  and  Coal- 
miners  —  trades  which  we  are  always  having  to  couple 
together — have  repeatedly  met  their  employers'  demands  for 
reduction  of  wages  by  an  equally  confident  demand  for  a 
restriction  of  the  output.  This  policy  dates  from  the  very 
beginning  of  the  century.  Thus,  to  quote  an  official  report 
of  1844,  "  It  can  scarcely  be  credited  by  one  calmly  investi- 
gating the  state  of  this  large  body  of  laborers,  that  many 
thousands  of  them — in  fact,  the  whole  of  the  colliers  and 
miners  in  Lanarkshire,  with  a  few  exceptions,  amounting  to 
1 6,000  men — have,  for  many  years  past  (since  the  repeal  of 
the  Combination  Laws  in  1825),  placed  themselves  under 
regulations  as  to  the  amount  of  their  labor,  which,  had  they 
been  attempted  to  be  enforced  by  the  authority  of  any 
government  whatsoever,  in  any  country  calling  itself  civilised, 
would  have  roused  the  indignation  of  every  thinking  man,  as 
against  an  act  of  the  most  intolerable  despotism.  And  yet 

1  In  our  History  of  Trade  Unionism  we  have  described  how,  for  a  few  years, 
a  small  number  of  unions,  mainly  in  the  coal  and  iron  industries,  accepted  the 
employers'  arguments,  and  agreed  to  the  celebrated  arrangement  of  the  Sliding 
Scale,  which  the  Coalminers  have  now  practically  abandoned.  We  refer  to  this 
method  of  adjusting  wages  in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Union- 
ism." Particulars  of  all  known  Sliding  Scales  are  given  in  Appendix  II.  of  the 
History  of  Trade  Unionism. 


Continuity  of  Employment  447 

these  regulations  were  intended  by  the  working  colliers  .  .  . 
for  the  maintenance  of  wages  at  a  fair  level,  for  their  protec- 
tion against  overwork,  and  against  an  overstocking  of  the 
market  of  labor  and  the  market  of  coal.  ...  A  certain  day's 
work,  called  the  *  darg,'  is  fixed,  which  the  colliers  themselves 
allow  no  one  to  exceed." * 

The  policy  of  regulating  the  output  of  coal  in  proportion 
to  the  demand  for  it  at  the  current  price  has  always  remained 
a  leading  principle  of  the  Coalminers.  The  "  darg,"  or  limit 
to  the  day's  product  of  the  individual  hewer,  has  at  no  time 
extensively  prevailed,  and  is  to-day  characteristic  not  of  good 
Trade  Union  districts,  but  only  of  the  half-organised  Ayrshire 
and  Lanarkshire  pits.  In  England  restriction  of  output  has 
taken  the  form  only  of  a  counter  proposal,  justifying  the 
miners'  refusal  to  lower  wages.2  When  the  coalowners  have 
pleaded  their  accumulating  stocks  of  coal  as  a  reason  why 
wages  and  prices  should  be  lowered,  in  order  to  stimulate 
demand,  the  miners  have  suggested  that  Supply  and  Demand 

1  Report  of  Commissioner  to  inquire  into  Coalmining,  No.  592  of  1844,  vol. 
xvii.  p.  31,  quoted  in  J.  H.  Burton's  Political  and  Social  Economy  (Edinburgh, 
1849).    In  one  or  two  old  piecework  trades — notably  some  branches  of  the  Potters 
and  Glass  Bottle  Makers — a  similar  limitation  of  individual  output  has  prevailed 
under  the  name  of  "stint"  or  "tantum."     "  In  our  light  metal  shops,"  wrote 
the  secretary  of  the  North  of  England  Glass  Bottle  Makers'  Society  in  1895, 
"  the  Society  has  a  tantum  fixed,  which  the  men  are  not  allowed  to  exceed  :  if 
they  do  it  is  paid  into  the  Society,  as  a  reference  to  the  reports  will  show.   .   .   . 
I  give  you  a  copy  of  the  tantum  for  light  metal  in  our  district  as  mentioned  : — 

Reputed  Quarts      .         ;.        .         .         .  no  dozen. 

10  oz.  Codd's          .....  105      ,, 

5  oz.  Codd's  .         .         .       -v        •         .  115      ,, 

Imperial  Pints         .          .          .         .          .  115      ,, 

Reputed  Pints  above  12  oz.      .         .         .  115      „ 
Do.       under  12  oz.,  no  restriction. 

All  bottles  made  in  excess  of  the  above  the  money  is  paid  into  the  funds  of  the 
Society." — Report  of  the  Rates  of  Wages,  Lists  of  Numbers,  etc.,  of  the  Glass 
Bottle  Makers  of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland  (Castleford,  1895),  P-  49- 

2  The  Rules  of  the  Miners'1  United  Association  of  the  County  of  Fife  (Dunferm- 
line,  1868)  refers  in  the  preamble  to  "  the  fearful  stocks  of  coal  which  have  accumu- 
lated in  the  county,  which  evil  stands  out  like  a  bold  monster,  to  defy  us  in 
having  our  just  rights."     The  Articles  of  Regulation  of  the   Operative   Collieries 
of  Lanark  and  Dumbarton  of  1825  declared  "that  there  should  never  be  allowed 
to  be  any  stock  of  coals  in  the  hands  of  any  of  the  masters." — See  Huskisson's 
Speeches  (London,  1831),  vol.  ii.  pp.  369,  371. 


448  Trade  Union  Function 

should  be  adjusted  rather  by  diminishing  the  output  than 
by  forcing  coal  upon  unwilling  buyers.  In  one  recent 
instance  the  Trade  Union  gave  a  practical  illustration  of  this 
policy.  In  March  1892  the  Miners'  Federation  saw  its 
members  threatened  with  a  reduction  of  wages  by  coal- 
owners  unable  to  keep  up  their  sales.  The  men  resolved 
to  "take  a  week's  holiday,"  with  the  result  that  the  stocks 
were  temporarily  diminished,  and  the  reduction  was  not 
insisted  on.1 

1  This  policy  of  restricting  the  output  has,  under  the  name  of  "  Limitation  of 
the  Vend,"  long  been  characteristic  of  the  coal  trade.  From  1771  to  1844,  a 
period  of  seventy-three  years,  there  existed,  almost  continuously,  a  systematic 
organisation  among  the  coalowners  of  the  Tyne  and  Wear  for  fixing  price  and 
output.  "  The  colliery  owners  met  annually  and  agreed  upon  what  was  called 
the  'basis,'  that  is,  the  proportion  which  each  colliery  should  sell  of  the  total 
'vend.'  They  met  monthly,  and  sometimes  fortnightly,  to  fix  what  was  called 
the  '  issue '  for  the  following  month.  There  was  an  understanding  as  to  the 
price  at  which  each  colliery  should  sell.  A  fine  of  from  35.  to  55.  per  Newcastle 
chaldron  was  paid  by  those  who  at  the  end  of  the  year  had  exceeded  their 
quantity,  and  this  was  received  by  those  who  were  short '  (D.  A.  Thomas).  The 
result  was  that  prices  were  greatly  and  continuously  raised.  It  appears  that  so 
long  as  the  arrangement  effected  an  actual  restriction  of  the  total  output,  it  worked 
satisfactorily  enough  to  the  coalowners.  But  eventually  each  coalowner  strove, 
by  opening  new  pits  and  increasing  their  capacity,  to  increase  his  own  "basis." 
The  arrangement  then  ceased  to  restrict  the  total  output,  and  became  only  one  of 
"sharing  work,"  which  came  to  an  end  in  1844  by  the  revolt  of  the  larger 
collieries,  who  desired  to  work  their  pits  to  the  full  capacity.  Particulars  are  to 
be  found  in  the  Reports  and  Evidence  of  the  Parliamentary  Committees  of  1800, 
1829,  1830,  and  1873  on  the  coal  trade  (G.  R.  Porter's  Progress  of  the  Nation, 
London,  pp.  283-286  of  1847  edition  ;  Cunningham's  Growth  of  English  Industry 
and  Commerce,  vol.  ii.  p.  463  ;  Some  Notes  on  the  Present  State  of  the  Coal 
Trade,  by  D.  A.  Thomas,  M.P.,  Cardiff,  1896).  Mr.  Thomas  proposes  to 
institute  a  similar  "  Limitation  of  the  Vend  "  for  South  Wales,  urging  that  if  each 
colliery  agreed  to  produce  only  its  allotted  quota  of  the  total  output,  prices  would 
be  automatically  maintained,  without  the  need  of  any  concerted  action  among 
the  sellers  as  to  price,  and  without  actually  limiting  the  total  supply  below  the 
demand  for  it  at  existing  prices.  This  proposal  seems  to  contain,  in  not 
providing  against  a  reckless  increase  in  the  number  and  capacity  of  pits,  the 
same  inherent  weakness  that  eventually  broke  up  the  Tyne  and  Wear  arrangement. 

The  coalowners  in  Westphalia  and  Pennsylvania  have  gone  farther.  The 
Rhenish  Westphalian  Coal  Syndicate  has,  since  1893,  conducted  all  sales  for  the 
Westphalian  coalowners,  fixing  both  price  and  output.  The  Coalowners' 
Association  of  Pennsylvania,  in  conjunction  with  the  great  railway  companies, 
has  an  essentially  similar  arrangement  for  the  supply  of  anthracite.  Sir  George 
Elliot's  bold  proposal  (described  in  the  Times  of  2Oth  September  1893)  °f  an 
amalgamation  of  all  the  coalmines  of  the  United  Kingdom  into  a  single  company 
of  ;£  1 1 0,000, ooo,  subject  to  a  government  control  over  rises  in  price,  may 
eventually  be  adopted  in  preference  to  a  merely  capitalist  trust. 


Continuity  of  Employment  449 

For  twenty  years  a  similar  policy  has  been  urged  by  the 
Cotton  Operatives  at  each  recurring  period  of  contraction  of 
trade.  In  the  great  depression  of  1878,  when  the  value  of 
English  exports  of  cotton  piece-goods  fell  no  less  than  17 
per  cent  below  those  of  1872,  the  employers  insisted  that 
only  by  a  10  per  cent  reduction  could  they  continue  their 
trade.  The  weavers  denied  that  any  such  reduction  would 
"  remove  the  glut  from  an  overstocked  cloth  market," 
especially  in  view  of  the  fact  that  the  quantity  of  piece-goods 
exported  was  no  less  than  before,  but  offered  to  give  way, 
provided  that  the  employers  would,  on  their  side,  consent 
to  put  all  the  mills  on  short  time,  so  as  to  stop  the  over- 
production.1 Again,  in  the  depression  of  1885,  the  employers 
pressed  for  a  reduction,  and  the  operatives — this  time  the 
spinners — formally  offered  to  "accept  a  reduction  of  10  per 
cent  and  four  days  a  week  ;  5  per  cent  and  five  days  ;  or 
full  rates  with  full  time." 2  "  The  employers,"  as  their  able 
secretary  explains,  "  looked  upon  this  as  a  fallacy,  knowing 
from  experience  that  short  time  meant  increased  cost  of 
production."  8 

We  do  not  propose  to  enter  into  the  complicated 
economic  arguments  which  are  urged  for  and  against  this 
policy  of  meeting  the  vicissitudes  of  demand  by  a  deliberately 
regulated  production.4  Whatever  may  be  said  in  favor  of 
Restriction  of  Output,  any  systematic  use  of  this  device  is 
out  of  the  reach  of  mere  associations  of  wage-earners.  They 
can,  of  course,  temporarily  stop  all  production  by  simultane- 
ously refusing  to  work,  as  in  a  strike  or  in  the  week's  holiday 
arbitrarily  taken  by  the  Miners'  Federation  in  1892.  But 

1  See  the  Cotton- weavers'  manifesto  of  June   1878,  given  in  the  History  of 
Trade  Unionism,  pp.  329,  330. 

2  Minutes   of  Sub-Committee,    Executive   Committee,  and    Representative 
Meeting  of  the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners,  June 
1885. 

3  Fifty   Years  of  the    Cotton  Trade,  by  Samuel  Andrew  (Oldham,    1887), 
p.  10. 

4  The  Trade  Union  position  in  the  controversy  of  1878  was  ably  maintained 
by  Mr.  (now  the  Right  Hon.)  John  Morley,  in  his  Over  Production ;  an  address 
delivered  at  the  Trade  Union  Congress,  1878  (Nottingham,  1879). 

VOL.  I  2  G 


450  Trade  Union  Function 

when  the  industrial  machine  is  in  motion,  any  direct  limita- 
tion of  output  is  beyond  the  power  of  the  Trade  Union.  A 
strongly-organised  union  might  insist  that  no  member  should 
produce  more  than  a  given  quantity  per  day  (the  Coal- 
miners'  "  darg "),  or  that  all  the  establishments  in  the  trade 
should  work  only  a  limited  number  of  hours  per  week  (the 
Cotton  Operatives'  "short  time").  But  neither  of  these 
expedients  has,  in  practice,  any  effective  result  in  diminishing 
the  total  amount  of  production  below  what  the  employers 
desire.  It  is  always  possible  to  employ  more  miners  in  the 
pit,  to  work  additional  seams,  or  even  to  open  up  new  pits. 
The  millowner  puts  in  additional  machines,  and  directly 
prices  rise  owing  to  the  rumour  of  restriction,  old  mills  are 
reopened  and  new  ones  erected.  Any  attempt  on  the  part 
of  the  wage -earners  to  limit  the  output  of  the  individual 
operative,  though  it  may  cause  inconvenience,  or  increase 
the  expense  of  carrying  on  the  industry,  has,  therefore,  no 
practical  effect  in  restricting  the  total  amount  that  will  be 
produced.  Hence,  though  the  English  Coalminers  and 
Cotton  Operatives  remain  firmly  convinced  that  it  would  be 
desirable  for  their  employers  to  restrict  production,  they 
have  taken  no  steps  to  effect  this  restriction  by  Trade 
Union  Regulation.1  The  Trade  Unionists  in  short,  like 
the  majority  of  English  employers,  have  hitherto  stood 
helpless  before  the  inscrutable  ebb  and  flow  of  demand,  and 
have  accepted  as  inevitable  the  corresponding  fluctuations 
of  work. 

Thwarted  in  their  efforts  to   secure  continuity  of  em- 
ployment, either  from  the  employer  or  from  the  consumer, 

1  Restriction  of  output  is,  in  fact,  an  employer's  device,  not  a  workman's,  and 
it  is  usually  practised  (as  in  the  Coalowners'  "Limitation  of  the  Vend"  or  an 
ordinary  Trust)  without  the  help  of  the  wage-earners,  though  occasionally  (as  in 
the  "Alliances"  of  the  Birmingham  bedstead  manufacturers  hereafter  described) 
with  the  co-operation  of  the  Trade  Union.  Its  economic  effect  is  incidentally 
referred  to  in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Economic  Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism." 
We  may  say  at  once  that,  from  the  workman's  point  of  view,  it  is  of  no  avail 
in  maintaining  wages  unless  it  is  accompanied  by  the  Common  Rule  of  the 
Standard  Rate,  and  that  with  such  a  Common  Rule  it  is  unnecessary  and 
useless. 


Continuity  of  Employment  451 

particular  Trade  Unions  have  turned  their  force  in  another 
direction.  If  they  cannot  protect  themselves  against  the 
fluctuating  demands  of  the  capitalist  and  the  consumer,  they 
can  at  any  rate  build  up  barriers  against  their  fellow-work- 
men. Hence,  we  find  certain  sections  of  the  Trade  Union 
world  of  to-day  clinging  to  the  mediaeval  expedients  of 
apprenticeship  and  limitation  of  the  recruits  to  a  trade, 
the  exclusion  of  women,  and  the  maintenance,  as  against 
other  workmen,  of  a  vested  interest  in  an  advantageous 
means  of  livelihood. 

It  is  significant  that  it  is  only  at  this  point  in  our  analysis 
of  Trade  Union  regulations  that  we  find  ourselves  face  to 
face  with  the  idea  of  "  monopoly."  The  Standard  Rate,  the 
Normal  Day,  and  a  safe  and  healthy  place  of  work  can  be 
simultaneously  enjoyed  by  the  entire  wage-earning  class  of 
the  country.  So  far  from  there  being  any  desire  that  these 
conditions  should  be  a  privilege  of  any  class  or  section,  the 
Trade  Unionists  claim  that,  on  any  of  these  points,  a  success- 
ful stand  made  by  one  union  renders  it  positively  easier  for 
other  grades  of  workmen  to  put  forward  similar  claims. 
When  the  contractors  and  master  builders  in  any  town  have 
been  induced  to  agree  to  definite  Standard  Rates  for  all  the 
bricklayers,  stonemasons,  and  carpenters  in  their  employment, 
they  are  predisposed  to  complete  the  arrangement  by  con- 
ceding a  Standard  Rate  even  to  the  laborers.  And  when 
the  leading  unions  in  a  town  press  the  Town  Council  either 
itself  to  pay  "  Trade  Union  wages,"  or  to  compel  its  con- 
tractors to  do  so,  this  demand  is  always  intended  to  apply 
equally  to  all  classes  of  wage-earners.  Still  more  is  this  the 
case  with  regard  to  the  Normal  Day,  which  almost  inevitably 
tends,  as  we  have  seen,  to  become  identical  for  all  classes 
of  operatives  in  the  same  establishment.  Finally,  all  the 
regulations  for  securing  the  sanitation  of  the  workplace  and 
the  prevention  of  accidents  necessarily  benefit  the  wage- 
earners  without  distinction  of  grade,  merit,  or  sex.  But  in 
the  regulations  with  which  we  deal  in  the  next  two  chapters, 
based  upon  the  idea  of  a  vested  interest  in  a  trade,  asserted 


452  Trade  Union  Function 

by  one  set  of  workmen  to  the  exclusion  of  others,  we  have 
a  claim  of  an  entirely  different  nature,  akin  to  those  put 
forward  by  the  holders  of  "  free-hold  offices,"  ecclesiastical 
benefices,  or  Civil  Service  appointments,  when  these  are 
threatened  with  abolition  or  reorganisation. 


CHAPTER    X 
THE    ENTRANCE   TO    A    TRADE 

THE  trade  clubs  of  eighteenth -century  handicraftsmen  re- 
garded the  limitation  of  apprentices  and  the  exclusion  of 
illegal  men  as  the  pivot  of  their  Trade  Unionism.  Down 
to  1814  the  policy  of  regulating  the  entrance  into  a  trade 
could  claim  the  sanction  of  law,  and  the  workmen's  organ- 
isations did  their  utmost  to  prevent  the  repeal  of  the  Statute 
of  Apprentices.1  Notwithstanding  the  legal  opening  of 
every  occupation,  the  Parliamentary  committees  of  1824-25 
and  1838,  and  the  Royal  Commission  of  1867  revealed 
numerous  cases  in  which  Trade  Unions  sought  to  regulate 
the  entrance  into  their  respective  trades.  It  has  accordingly 
been  assumed  by  many  writers  that  the  policy  of  restricting 
numbers  forms  an  integral  part  of  Trade  Unionism.  In  the 
following  pages  we  shall  examine  how  far  this  assumption 
holds  true  of  the  Trade  Unionism  of  the  present  day  ;  we 
shall  estimate  the  number  of  Trade  Unions  that  aim  at 
restricting  the  entrance  into  their  trades ;  and  we  shall 
analyse  the  actual  working  of  such  regulations  in  order  to 
discover  how  far  they  succeed  in  effecting  their  object.  For 
the  purpose  of  this  analysis  it  will  be  convenient  to  classify 
all  rules  dealing  with  admission  to  a  trade  under  the  four 
heads  of  Apprenticeship,  Limitation  of  Boy-Labor,  Pro- 
gression within  the  Trade,  and  the  Exclusion  of  Women. 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  54-56. 


454  Trade  Union  Function 


(a)  Apprenticeship 

The  Trade  Union  Regulations  as  to  Apprenticeship, 
unlike  those  for  maintaining  the  Standard  Rate,  were  not 
invented  by  the  Trade  Unions  themselves.  They  can  scarcely 
be  said  even  to  have  been  modified  or  developed,  like  the 
workmen's  policy  with  regard  to  new  processes  and  machin- 
ery, by  Trade  Union  experience.  So  far  as  any  system  of 
apprenticeship  still  lingers  in  the  Trade  Union  world,  this  is, 
in  form  and  in  purpose,  practically  identical  with  that  which 
prevailed  long  before  Trade  Unionism  was  heard  of.1 

The  modern  Trade  Unionist  has,  in  this  matter  of  ap- 
prenticeship, inherited  two  distinct  and  contradictory  tradi- 
tions. We  have,  on  the  one  hand,  the  remnants  of  the 
formal,  legal,  indentured  apprenticeship  to  the  master-crafts- 
man, with  its  reciprocal  obligations  between  the  employer  and 
his  apprentices.  The  master  undertook  to  teach  the  boys 
all  the  mysteries  of  his  craft.  The  apprentices  undertook  to 
serve  for  a  long  term  for  wages  below  the  market  rate. 
As  Paley  tersely  puts  it,  "  instruction  is  their  hire."  2  Round 
this  "  apprenticeship  to  the  employer,"  descended  to  us  from 
the  ordinances  made  by  the  master-craftsmen's  gilds,  there 
had  grown  up  already  in  mediaeval  times  a  whole  series 
of  restrictive  conditions,  the  exaction  of  fees  or  premiums, 

1  With  the  system  of  apprenticeship  considered  as  part  of  the  organisation  of 
mediaeval  industry,  we  make  no  attempt  to  deal.      There  has  been  little  detailed 
study  either  of  the  facts  or  of  the  economic  results  of  this  system  in  the  United 
Kingdom.     Adam  Smith's  celebrated  denunciation  ( Wealth  of  Nations,  Book  I. 
chap.   x.   part  2)  has  been  criticised   by  several  of  his  commentators,  notably 
by   Dr.    William    Playfair    in    the    edition   of    1805 ;    see    also    the    latter's 
pamphlet,  A  Letter  to  the  .  .   .  Lords  and  Commons  .   .  .  on  the  Advantages  of 
Apprenticeships  (London,  1814).     The  subject  has  also  been  dealt  with  by  Dr. 
L.   Brentano  in  his  Arbeitergilden  der  Gegenwart  (Leipzig,   1871),  vol.  ii.  pp. 
143-155.     A  pamphlet,  The   Origin,  Objects,  and  Operation  of  the  Apprentice 
Laws  (London,  1814),  preserved  in  the  Pamphleteer,  vol.  iii.,  gives  the  masters' 
case  for  freedom.      See  Dr.  Cunningham's  Growth  of  English  Industry  and  Com- 
merce, vol.  ii.  p.  578,  etc.  ;  and  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  54-56,  etc.     A 
recent  article,  "  The  Fair  Number  of  Apprentices  in  a  Trade,"  by  C.  P.  Sanger, 
Economic  Journal,  December  1895,  gives  useful  mathematical  formulae. 

2  Moral  and  Political  Philosophy,  Book  III.  part  i.  chap.  xi.  (  "Apprentice- 
ship"). 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  455 

rigid  limits  of  age,  a  definite  long  term  of  servitude,  and  a 
limitation  of  the  number  of  apprentices  permitted  to  each 
employer.1  These  regulations,  designed  for  the  double 
purpose  of  securing  technical  training  and  protecting  the 
craftsmen  in  their  economic  monopoly,  have  their  repre- 
sentatives in  modern  Trade  Unionism.  On  the  other  hand, 
we  find,  alongside  this  formal  apprenticeship,  the  custom  of 
"  patrimony,"  that  is  to  say,  a  privilege  enjoyed  from  time 
immemorial,  by  the  journeymen  in  certain  occupations,  of 
bringing  their  own  sons  into  the  trade,  and  themselves 
informally  instructing  them  in  the  processes  of  the  craft. 
This  "  apprenticeship  to  the  journeyman,"  hitherto  unde- 
scribed  by  historian  or  economist,  stands  in  sharp  contrast 
to  the  other  system.  It  seems  never  to  have  been  regulated 
by  law  or  gild  ordinance,  and  to  have  rested  only  on  the 
customs  of  the  workshop.  It  was,  in  fact,  not  a  rival  system, 
but  a  privileged  exemption  from  the  operation  of  the  law. 
The  craftsman  father  could  bring  his  son  into  the  workshop 
at  what  age  he  chose,  and  for  what  period  he  deemed  fit. 
He  needed  no  legal  indentures  or  formal  contract.  He 
paid  no  fee  or  tax,  and  was  usually  subject  to  no  supervision 
from  the  authorities  of  the  trade.  He  could  sometimes 
introduce  all  his  sons  in  succession,  or  even  simultaneously, 
without  restriction  of  numbers.  Thus,  the  characteristic 
idea  of  apprenticeship  to  the  journeyman  has  little  reference 
to  the  well-being  of  the  trade  as  a  whole,  but  is  essentially 
that  of  personal  privilege,  based  upon  an  hereditary  vested 
interest.  This  tradition  of  "  patrimony,"  which  is  still 

1  The  "masterpiece,"  the  production  of  which  was  a  condition  of  admission 
to  journeymanship,  does  not  seem  to  have  been  a  feature  of  English  apprentice- 
ship. The  "  wander j  ah  re,"  or  customary  years  of  travel  from  town  to  town  at 
its  close,  were  likewise  unknown,  as  a  regular  custom,  in  this  country.  These 
and  other  differences  warn  us,  in  the  absence  of  English  evidence,  against  assum- 
ing that  apprenticeship  in  England  ran  the  same  course,  or  led  to  the  same  con- 
sequences as  the  system  in  France,  Germany,  and  the  Rhine  Valley,  as  described, 
for  instance,  in  Levasseur,  Histoire  des  Classes  Ouvritres  en  France ;  Fagniez, 
Etudes  sur  ?  Industrie  et  la  classe  industrielle  a  Paris ;  Martin -Saint -Leon, 
Histoire  des  Corporations  de  Metiers ;  Schanz,  Zur  Geschichte  der  Deutschen 
Gesellenverbande  im  Mittelallef  ;  or  Schmoller,  Die  Strassburger  Tucker  und 
Weberzunft. 


456  Trade  Union  Function 

strong  in  many  trades,  constantly  affects  or  nullifies,  by 
its  laxity,  irregularity,  and  inequality,  the  deliberate  regu- 
lation and  systematic  uniformity  aimed  at  by  the  system 
of  apprenticeship  by  legal  indentures  and  its  modern  de- 
rivatives. 

We  shall  best  understand  the  character  of  these  two 
streams  of  tradition  by  examining  typical  instances  of 
existing  Trade  Union  Regulations  in  particular  industries. 
By  far  the  best  modern  example  of  -an  effective  system  of 
apprenticeship  to  the  employer  is  that  now  embodied  in  the 
elaborate  treaty  concluded  between  the  United  Society  of 
Boilermakers  and  Iron -shipbuilders  and  nearly  all  the 
master  shipbuilders  of  the  United  Kingdom.  Here  we 
have  a  formal  code  of  rules  precisely  regulating  the  ad- 
mission of  apprentices  in  all  the  ports  of  the  kingdom. 
There  is,  to  begin  with,  a  clear  distinction  between  the  lad 
engaged  as  a  "  plater's  marker "  or  "  rivet  boy,"  who  is 
taught  nothing,  but  is  paid  full  wages,  and  the  apprentice 
who  is  taught  the  trade.  When  a  boy  is  taken  as  an  ap- 
prentice, which  must  in  any  case  be  before  he  is  eighteen 
years  of  age,  he  enters  into  formal  indentures  or  written 
agreement,  by  which  he  is  bound  to  serve  for  five  years,  at 
specified  low  rates  of  wages,  which  are,  from  first  to  last, 
far  less  than  he  could  earn  as  a  rivet  boy.  In  return,  the 
employer  formally  contracts  to  give  him  adequate  instruc- 
tion as  a  plater  and  rivetter.  No  apprentice  may  leave 
his  employer  before  the  expiration  of  the  five  years'  term 
of  servitude,  unless  with  express  permission  in  writing,  and 
the  Trade  Union  is  able  to  enforce  the  most  rigid  boycott 
of  any  lad  who  runs  away  from  his  indentures.  The  num- 
ber of  apprentices  taken  by  any  firm  is  not  to  exceed  two 
to  every  seven  journeymen,  the  ratio  being  computed  on 
the  average  number  employed  during  the  past  five  years, 
with  special  consideration  for  rapidly  growing  establish- 
ments and  other  exceptional  cases.  Finally,  the  engage- 
ment of  apprentices  is  left  absolutely  and  exclusively  to  the 
employers,  no  journeyman  having  any  right  to  bring  his 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  457 

own  son  into  the  trade  otherwise  than  as  an  employer's 
apprentice.1 

Here,  it  will  be  seen,  we  have  a  system  of  apprentice- 
ship to  the  employers  reproducing,  in  all  essential  features, 
the  typical  educational  servitude  of  the  Middle  Ages.  To 
become  a  boilermaker-apprentice  the  modern  rivet-boy  fore- 
goes often  half  his  actual  earnings,  and  finds  himself  at  the 
age  of  twenty-one  or  twenty-two  getting  only  ten  shillings  a 
week.  On  the  other  hand,  the  employer  encumbers  his  yard 
with  a  raw  lad,  who  instead  of  being  kept  to  mere  mechanical 
routine,  has  to  be  always  trying  his  hand  at  work  for  which 
he  is  not  yet  competent.  And  once  entered  on,  these  reci- 
procal obligations  are  practically  binding  on  both  parties. 
The  apprentice,  it  is  true,  no  longer  becomes  a  member  of 
the  employer's  family,  and  neither  party  looks  to  the  law,  "or 
to  any  public  authority,  to  enforce  the  contract.  But  these 
elaborate  regulations  are  much  more  than  mere  Trade  Union 
by-laws.  A  formal  treaty  signed,  not  only  by  a  Trade 
Union  practically  co-extensive  with  the  industry,  but  also 
by  nine-tenths  of  the  employers  is,  to  all  intents  and  pur- 
poses, a  coercive  law.  It  is,  in  fact,  practically  impossible 
for  any  youth  to  enter  the  iron-shipbuilding  trade  in  Great 
Britain  except  in  the  way  prescribed  by  the  united  masters 
and  men. 

To  see  in  full  force  the  other  stream  of  tradition — 
apprenticeship  to  the  journeyman — we  must  turn  from  the 
great  modern  industry  of  iron-shipbuilding  to  the  forty  or 

1  Memorandum  of  Arrangement  re  the  Apprentice  Question  between  the 
Employers  and  the  Committee  of  the  Boilermakers  and  Iron-shipbuilders*  Society r, 
nth  October  1893,  signed  by  Col.  H.  Dyer  (of  Armstrong's  Works,  Elswick) 
as  Chairman  of  the  Employers'  Committee,  and  Mr.  R.  Knight  as  General 
Secretary,  on  behalf  of  the  Trade  Union.  The  United  Society  of  Boilermakers 
strove,  at  first,  for  a  ratio  of  one  apprentice  to  five  journeymen,  which  some 
employers  thought  insufficient  to  keep  up  the  trade  (see  Memorandum,  by  Mr.  J. 
Inglis,  of  the  firm  of  A.  and  J.  Inglis,  Glasgow ;  and  his  Evidence  before  the 
Royal  Commission  on  Labor,  C.  6194,  iii.  Group  A;  more  fully  explained  by 
him  in  The  Apprentice  Question,  a  paper  printed  in  the  Proceedings  of  the 
Philosophical  Society  of  Glasgow,  1894).  From  Mr.  Inglis's  latest  paper  and  from 
Mr.  Sanger's  article  already  cited,  we  gather  that  the  present  ratio  of  two  to 
seven  is,  according  to  the  best  available  data,  a  "  fair  "  one,  providing,  not  only 
for  the  maintenance,  but  also  for  a  normal  increase  of  the  trade. 


458  Trade  Union  Function 

fifty  ancient  handicrafts  composing  the  Sheffield  cutlery 
trade.  Three  hundred  years  ago  apprentices  in  Sheffield 
were  formally  indentured  to  the  master  craftsman,  enrolled 
at  the  Court  Leet,  and  at  the  end  of  their  prescribed  term 
of  servitude  publicly  admitted  to  the  trade.  But  as  far  back 
as  1565  we  find  existing  an  exemption  of  craftsmen's  sons 
from  all  fees,  formalities,  and  indentures.1  What  was  then 
apparently  an  exception  has  to-day  become  practically  the 
only  avenue  to  employment.  Apprenticeship  to  the  em- 
ployer, now  become  a  capitalist  giver-out  of  work,  has  almost 
entirely  disappeared.  The  journeyman,  who  seldom  works 
on  his  employer's  premises,  engages  his  own  boy  assistant, 
who  is  nowadays  never  formally  indentured  or  bound  for 
any  specified  period.  Hereditary  succession  has  become 
the  dominant  idea.  "  No  journeyman,"  say  the  Britannia 
Metal  Smiths,  "  shall  take  an  apprentice  except  such  be  his 
own  or  a  journeyman's  son,  who  must  be  under  seventeen 
years  of  age,  but  he  cannot  have  an  apprentice  in  addition 
to  his  own  son  or  sons."  2  This  is  put  more  curtly  by  the 
Razor  Hafters.  "  That  no  boys  be  admitted  to  the  trade 
except  members'  sons."  a 

When  the  ordinary  method  of  recruiting  a  trade  is  for 
fathers  to  instruct  their  own  sons,  any  collective  regulation  of 
apprenticeship  becomes  practically  impossible.  The  father 
brings  in  his  boy  when  he  finds  it  convenient,  teaches  him 
what  he  chooses,  and  pays  him  anything  or  nothing  as  may 
be  arranged  between  them.  The  enforcement  of  a  definite 
period  of  educational  servitude  becomes  impracticable.  More- 
over, any  effective  limitation  of  the  number  has  to  be  given 
up.  The  commonly  accepted  ratio  of  apprentices  to  adult 
workmen  in  modern  industry  is  one  boy  to  every  four  or 
five  men.  But  every  Sheffield  craftsman  would  feel  it  an 
intolerable  grievance  not  to  be  able  to  bring  his  own  son 

1  The  History  of  Hallamshire,  by  Joseph  Hunter  (London,  1869),  p.  150; 
see  the  excellent  account  of  the  trade  up  to  1860  by  Frank  Hill,  in  the  Social 
Science  Report  on  Trade  Societies  and  Strikes  (London,  1860),  pp.  521-586. 

2  Rules  of  the  Britannia  Metal  Smiths'1  Provident  Society  (Sheffield,  1888). 

3  Rules  of  the  Razor  Hafters'  Trade  Protection  Society  (Sheffield,  1892),  p.  6. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  459 

into  his  trade.  Hence  the  most  restrictive  of  the  Sheffield 
rules  allows  each  workman  of  a  certain  age  to  have  at  all 
times  one  apprentice  of  his  own.  Usually,  as  with  the 
Scythe  Grinders,  though  the  childless  journeyman  may  teach 
only  one  son  of  another  member,  the  happy  father  has  the 
privilege  of  bringing  all  his  boys  up  to  his  own  craft.  In 
some  of  the  Sheffield  trades  we  find  the  workmen  endeavor- 
ing to  restrict  the  numbers  entering  the  craft,  but  the  idea 
of  hereditary  right  to  the  trade  makes  these  attempts  take  a 
peculiar  and  futile  form.  The  Wool  Shear  Grinders,  the 
Razor  Hafters,  and  the  Edge  Tool  Forgers l  among  others 
compel  the  adult  craftsman  to  wait  seven  years  before  he 
brings  in  a  boy ;  the  Razor  Grinders  add  two  years  more, 
making  the  minimum  age  thirty ;  whilst  other  clubs  fix 
twenty-five  or  twenty-seven  as  the  age  before  which  "  no 
member  shall  take  an  apprentice." 2  In  exceptional  cases 
some  attempt  is  also  made  to  get  back  the  old  idea  of  a 
genuine  period  of  educational  servitude,  and  formal  testing 
of  competency.  The  Britannia  Metal  Smiths  have  a  rule 
that  "  any  journeyman  having  a  son  or  an  apprentice  shall 
not  leave  him  to  work  to  himself.  If  he  leave  him,  he  must 
put  him  to  some  other  journeyman,  to  complete  his  time, 
unless  he  first  obtain  the  sanction  of  a  general  meeting,"  and 
"  every  boy  on  completing  his  apprenticeship  shall  be  re- 
ported upon  by  the  men  working  at  the  firm  as  to  his 
abilities,  before  he  is  accepted  by  the  Trade.  If  it  be  found 
that  the  said  boy  is  incompetent  as  a  workman,  the  Com- 
mittee shall  institute  an  inquiry,  and,  if  possible,  to  ascertain 
the  cause,  and  take  the  necessary  steps  to  prevent  a  similar 
misfortune." 3 

1  Rules  of  the  Edge  Tool  Forgers'  Union  (Sheffield,  1873),  p.  6. 

2  Similar  limitations  are  to  be  found  in  gild  ordinances.      Thus  the  ordinances 
of  the  Gild  of  the  Tailors  of  Exeter  declare  that  a  newly-made  freeman  shall  be 
allowed  to  have  "  the  first  yeere  butt  oon  seruauant ;  the  second  yeere  II ;  the 
nird  in  ;  and  a  prentise  if  he  be  able "  (English   Gilds,  by  Toulmin  Smith, 
p.   316).     And   the   Ordinances  of  the   Shearmen   of  London,   made   in   1350, 
declare  "  that  no  one  of  this  trade  shall  receive  any  apprentice  if  he  be  not  a 
freeman  of  the  City  himself,  and  have  been  so  for  a  term  of  seven  years  at  least." 
— Riley's  Memorials  of  London  and  London  Life  (London,  1868),  p.  247. 

3  Rules  of  the  Britannia  Metal  Smiths'1  Provident  Society  (Sheffield, 


460  Trade  Union  Function 

Among  the  Stonemasons  we  find  a  formal  apprenticeship 
to  the  employer  coexisting  with  the  custom  of  Patrimony.1 
The  following  detailed  description  of  the  way  in  which  the 
trade  is  actually  recruited  at  the  present  day,  given  to  us  by 
a  trustworthy  and  intelligent  member  of  the  union,  has  been 
confirmed  by  our  own  investigations.  "  The  printed  Rules  of 
the  Stonemasons  as  to  apprentices  vary  from  town  to  town. 
Usually  they  include  a  limit  of  o^eboy  to  fivep£^six_rnen, 
and  require  that,  after  working  three"  months^atthe  trade, 
the  lad  must  be  actually  bound  apprentice  for  a  period  of 
five  or  seven  years.  Indentures  are  not  insisted  on,  but  some 
sort  of  agreement  is  usual,  and  these  boys  are,  of  course, 
always  '  to  the  employer/  These  rules,  which  are  generally 
yery  strictly  enforced,  apply,  however,  only  to  outside  ordinary 
boys  who  are  brought  into  the  trade.  In  addition  to  these, 
every  mason  is  permitted  to  bring  as  many  of  his  sons  as  he 
likes  into  the  trade,  and  teach  them  without  any  regulations 
or  apprenticeship.  Usually  the  man  keeps  his  son  at  work 
as  a  telegraph  boy,  or  otherwise,  until  he  is  sixteen  or  seven- 
teen years  of  age,  and  strong  enough  to  enter  the  trade  and 
become  useful.  Then  he  is  brought  into  the  shop  and  works 
for  the  employer  as  an  improver.  The  men  always  push  their 
sons  forward  as  rapidly  as  possible,  and  insist  on  their  getting 

Judging  by  the  context  the  rule  applies  primarily  to  employer's  apprentices.  In 
some  of  the  Sheffield  trades  the  gradual  transformation  into  factory  industries  has 
led  to  boys  being  apprenticed  also  to  the  capitalist  employer.  The  number  of 
these  apprentices  is  strictly  limited  by  the  Trade  Unions,  and  even  here  the 
restriction  retains  traces  of  the  paternal  type.  Thus  the  Britannia  Metal  Smiths 
have  a  rule  that  ' '  no  master  shall  have  more  than  one  apprentice  at  one  time  ; 
if  two  or  more  partners  they  can  have  one  each  ;  and  for  limited  companies,  for 
the  first  ten  men  or  fractional  part  thereof  one  boy,  from  eleven  to  twenty-five 
men  two  boys,  and  so  raising  one  boy  to  every  fifteen  additional  men." 

1  This  custom  of  Patrimony  in  English  trade  deserves  further  study,  especially 
in  reference  to  its  resemblance  to  the  common  gild  and  municipal  regulation 
permitting  the  son  of  a  freeman,  without  other  qualification,  to  take  up  his  own 
freedom  of  the  gild  or  the  city  on  coming  of  age.  We  know  of  no  evidence 
actually  connecting  the  Trade  Union  custom  with  the  gild  or  municipal  practice. 
Besides  the  Stonemasons  and  the  Sheffield  trades,  traces  of  the  privilege  are  to 
be  found  also  among  the  old  unions  of  Woolstaplers,  Millwrights,  Coopers, 
Block-printers,  Skinners,  Beamers,  Twisters,  and  Drawers,  Warpers,  Spanish  and 
Morocco  Leather  Finishers,  and  a  few  other  handicrafts.  It  was  formally 
abolished  by  the  London  Society  of  Compositors  at  the  revision  of  their  rules 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  461 

full  man's  pay  the  moment  they  are  entrusted  with  a  man's 
work  to  do.  In  point  of  fact  the  trade  is  almost  entirely 
recruited  by  this  means.  Very  few  lads  are  bound,  and  very 
few  outside  boys  enter  the  trade.  The  employers  are  not 
anxious  to  have  them,  because  for  the  first  three  or  four 
years  they  earn  nothing  and  spoil  a  good  deal  of  stone. 
^Drf  the  other  hand,  the  men  object  to  them  because  for  the 
last  year  or  two  they  are  doing  a  man's  work  at  a  good  deal 
below  man's  pay,  while  the  member's  son  entering  the  trade 
is  pushed  forward  as  rapidly  as  possible,  and  compelled  by 
the  men  to  demand  the  man's  rate  as  soon  as  he  is  a  capable 
workman,  or  else  leave  the  shop  and  go  elsewhere.  .  .  .  The 
rule  does  not  in  effect  amount  to  any  limitation  in  the  number 
of  learners.  Men  have  been  known  to  bring  up  as  many  as 
six  or  seven  sons  to  the  trade,  and  such  a  course  is  not 
resented  by  the  others.  Hence  there  is  no  complaint  of 
undermanning  the  trade  ever  heard.  In  Cornwall  and  some 
other  quarrying  districts,  where  the  men  are  paid  piecework, 
the  learners  are  absolutely  confined  to  sons  of  members,  and 
they  work  direct  for  their  father  or  other  workman,  and  never 
for  the  employer.  But  there  is  no  other  limit,  and  no  fixed 
period  of  servitude  enforced."  l 

in  1879.  Continental  history  reveals  what  may,  perhaps,  be  an  analogous 
custom,  according  to  which  craftsmen's  sons  were  admitted  to  the  freedom  of 
the  craft  after  a  shorter  period  of  apprenticeship,  an  easier  test  of  proficiency, 
and  lower  fees ;  see,  for  instance,  Du  Cellier,  Histoire  des  Classes  Laborieuses  en 
France^  p.  219. 

1  This  is  one  of  the  instances  in  which  a  mere  inspection  of  printed  documents, 
or  even  a  desultory  questioning  of  Trade  Union  officials,  would  only  mislead  the 
student.  There  is  a  common  impression  that  the  Stonemasons  strictly  enforce  a 
long  period  of  educational  servitude,  and  insist  on  formal  indentures.  This  is 
frankly  stated  to  any  inquirer  by  the  officials  of  the  union.  But  it  does  not  occur 
to  them  to  explain  that  this  is  not  the  way  in  which  the  trade  is  actually  recruited. 
Nor  do  we  find  any  mention  of  hereditary  privilege,  or  indeed  any  reference  to 
the  regulation  of  apprenticeship,  in  any  of  the  editions  of  the  rules  issued  since 
the  Royal  Commission  inquiry  of  1868.  To  find  any  indication  of  the  actual 
practice  we  must  go  back  to  the  earlier  rules.  The  Laws  of  the  Friendly  Society 
of  Operative  Stonemasons  (Bolton,  1867)  contain,  at  p.  32,  the  following  clause, 
elaborated  from  similar  clauses  in  previous  editions:  "  Boys  entering  the  trade 
on  no  occasion  to  exceed  sixteen  years  of  age,  and  to  be  legally  bound  apprentice 
till  twenty-one  years  of  age.  No  boy  to  work  more  than  three  months  without 
being  legally  bound.  .  .  .  The  sons,  or  step-sons  of  masons  be  allowed  the  scale 


462  Trade  Union  Function 

The  case  of  the  Stonemasons  will  bring  home  to  the 
reader  the  manner  in  which  the  Trade  Union  regulations 
as  to  apprenticeship  elude  any  scientific  classification.  Here 
we  have  a  trade  which  seems,  at  first  sight,  to  be  strictly 
regulated  in  numbers,  age,  and  fixed  period  of  apprenticeship, 
all  formally  defined  and  rigidly  enforced.  From  this  point 
of  view  it  belongs  to  the  same  class  as  the  United  Society 
of  Boilermakers.  Closer  scrutiny  reveals,  however,  the 
presence,  not  of  formal  indentures,  reciprocal  obligations, 
fixed  period  of  servitude  and  limitation  of  numbers,  but  of 
the  laxity  characterising  the  hereditary  right  of  all  crafts- 
men's sons  to  scramble  up  into  journeymen  as  best  they  can, 
insisting  all  the  time  on  getting  the  full  market  rate  of 
wages  for  boy-labor.  Indeed,  if  we  took  the  extreme  case 
of  Cornwall,  or  other  quarrying  districts,  where  the  journey- 
man takes  the  apprentice,  we  should  have  an  exact  repro- 
duction of  the  type  presented  by  the  Sheffield  trades. 

We  have  chosen  the  Boilermakers,  the  Sheffield  cutlers, 
and  the  Stonemasons  for  special  description,  because  they 
comprise  between  them  by  far  the  majority  of  workmen  who 
systematically  enforce  any  apprenticeship  regulations  at  all. 
All  the  other  trades  in  which  any  effective  regulation  of 
numbers  exists,  do  not  together  include  as  many  numbers  as 
the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers.1  But  it  is  among  these 
smaller  unions  that  we  find  some  of  the  most  stringent 
limitations.  Thus,  whilst  the  Boilermakers  allow  two 
apprentices  to  seven  journeymen,  the  Felt  Hat  Makers2  and 
the  Flint  Glass  Cutters  8  have  one  to  five  only ;  the  Litho- 
graphic Printers  permit  one  to  five,  but  with  a  maximum  of 

of  initiation,  the  same  as  legal  apprentices  at  the  age  of  eighteen  years.  .  .  .  No 
boys  to  be  admitted  into  this  society  .  .  .  except  they  have  been  legally  bound, 
or  are  masons'  sons  or  step-sons. " 

1  Among  them  may  be  mentioned    the    hand    papermakers,    gold-beaters, 
basketmakers,    brushmakers,   coopers,    sailmakers,    woolstaplers,     calico    block- 
printers,  and  block-cutters — all  characteristically  old-fashioned  handicrafts. 

2  Rules  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of -Journeymen   Felt  Hatters  (Denton, 
1890),  p.  26. 

3  Amended  Laws  of  the   United  Flint  Glass  Cutters'  Mutual  Assistance  and 
Protective  Society  (Birmingham,  1887),  p.  19. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  463 

six  in  any  one  firm  j1  the  Flint  Glass  Makers  allow  one  to 
six  ; 2  the  Trimming  Weavers  of  Leek  declare  that  there 
shall  be  only  one  "  to  every  seven  going  looms  "  ; 3  and  the 
same  ratio  of  one  learner  to  seven  journeymen  is  prescribed 
by  the  Nottingham  Lace  Trade.4  The  old  -  established 
union  of  Silk  Hat  Makers  declares  that  any  manufacturer 
"  employing  three  journeymen  and  having  been  in  business 
twelve  months,  shall  be  entitled  to  one  apprentice,  and  for 
ten  men,  two  apprentices  ;  and  one  for  every  ten  men  in 
addition  to  that  number,"  and  "  that  employers'  sons  be 
reckoned  as  other  apprentices,  and  not  additional  as  hereto- 
fore." 5  Finally,  the  Yorkshire  Stuff  Pressers  insist  that  "  in 
any  one  shop  the  number  of  apprentices  shall  not  exceed 
one  to  every  ten  men,"  6  and  this  extreme  limitation  is  also 
insisted  on  by  our  old  friends  the  Pearl  Button  Makers, 
though  the  fact  is  not  mentioned  in  the  rules. 

The  apprenticeship  regulations  that  we  have  so  far 
described  have  one  characteristic  in  common.  The  elaborate 
national  treaty  of  the  Boilermakers,  the  stringent  exclusive- 
ness  of  the  Pearl  Button  Makers,  the  hereditary  succession 
of  the  Sheffield  trades,  and  the  curiously  duplex  system  of 
the  Stonemasons  are  all  actually  enforced  in  their  respective 
trades.  It  is  just  this  characteristic  of  reality  which  makes 
these  instances  exceptional  in  the  Trade  Union  world  of 
to-day.  Other  unions  retain  in  their  books  of  rules  a  more 
or  less  formal  definition  of  apprenticeship,  and  a  vote  of  the 
members  would  at  any  time  reveal  an  overwhelming  majority 
theoretically  in  favor  of  the  strictest  regulations  of  entrance. 

1  Rules  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Lithographic  Printers  of  Great  Britain 
and  Ireland  (Manchester,  1887),  p.  26. 

2  Rules  and  Regulations  of  the  National  Flint  Glass  Makers1  Sick  and  Friendly 
Society  of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland  (Manchester,  1890),  p.  19. 

3  Rules  of  the  Associated  Trimming  Weaver?  Society  (Leek,  1893),  p.  5. 

4  Prices  to  be  paid  for  various  classes  of  goods  in  the  Levers  Branch  of  the 
Lace  Trade  (Nottingham,  1893),  p.  47.     The  same  rule  obtains  in  the  other 
branches  of  the  trade. 

6  Rules  of  the  Journeymen  Hatters*  Fair  Trade  Union  of  Great  Britain  and 
Ireland  (London,  1891),  p.  46. 

6  Rules  of  the  Leeds,  Halifax,  and  Bradford  Stuff  Presser?  Trades  Union 
Society  (Bradford,  1888),  p.  23. 


464  Trade  Union  Function 

And  yet  in  these  same  trades  we  find  the  actual  conditions  of 
entrance  so  unregulated  that  the  ranks  of  the  Trade  Unionists 
themselves  are  largely  recruited  by  men  who  have  not  come 
in  by  the  recognised  gate.  Typical  instances  are  afforded 
by  the  printing  and  engineering  industries. 

The  case  of  the  Compositors  is  specially  significant.  We 
have  here  a  handicraft  requiring  no  small  degree  of  education 
and  manual  dexterity,  which  has  ranked,  from  the  outset,  as 
a  highly-skilled  craft.  During  the  eighteenth  century  a 
seven  years'  term  of  apprenticeship  was  universal,  and  the 
local  trade  clubs  at  the  beginning  of  the  present  century 
unhesitatingly  excluded  from  membership  and  employment 
any  person  who  presumed  to  come  into  the  trade  through  any 
but  the  traditional  avenue.  Nor  has  the  trade  become  any 
easier  to  learn.  Neither  machinery  nor  division  of  labor 
has  yet  enabled  the  capitalist  employer  to  split  up  the  old 
craft  into  sections,  each  calling  only  for  a  low  grade  of  skill. 
Employers  and  workmen  still  agree  that  the  only  way  to 
attain  proficiency  is  for  a  boy  to  be  put  through  a  prolonged 
course  of  actual  technical  instruction  in  a  number  of  separate 
processes,  from  deciphering  manuscripts  to  "  displaying " 
advertisements.1  Accordingly,  a  large  proportion  of  the  best 
employers  in  each  generation  have  cordially  acquiesced  in 
the  attempt  made  by  the  Compositors'  Trade  Unions  to 
maintain  the  long  period  of  formal  servitude,  and  have  often 
not  objected  to  a  reasonable  limitation  of  the  number  of 
apprentices.  Yet  to-day  it  is  probable  that  a  very  consider- 
able proportion  of  the  men  who  obtain  work  as  compositors, 
and  join  Compositors' Trade  Unions,  have  undergone  no  period 
of  educational  servitude  at  all,  with  or  without  indentures, 
and  have  "  picked  up  "  such  knowledge  of  the  trade  as  they 
possess  whilst  earning  a  full  market  rate  of  wages.  What 
is  of  even  more  importance  from  the  Trade  Unionist  point 
of  view,  the  attempt  to  set  any  limit  to  the  total  number  of 
persons  entering  the  trade  has  totally  failed. 

1  The  most  improved  machine,  the  linotype,  demands,  indeed,  an  even  higher 
level  of  skill  and  a  more  varied  proficiency  than  that  of  the  compositor  at  case. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  465 

This  failure  of  the  Compositors'  Trade  Unions  to  carry 
out  their  apprenticeship  regulations  is  mainly  due  to  the 
remarkable  spread  of  the  printing  industry  during  the  present 
century.  In  the  case  of  the  Boilermakers  the  rapid  increase 
of  the  industry  has  progressively  strengthened  the  union, 
and  has,  in  particular,  resulted  in  the  actual  enforcement  of 
a  genuine  apprenticeship  system.  But  the  development  of 
iron -shipbuilding  has  taken  place  almost  exclusively  in 
gigantic  establishments,  carried  on  by  a  distinct  class  of 
employers.  The  printing  trade,  on  the  other  hand,  once 
concentrated  in  half  a  dozen  towns,  has  to-day  crept  into 
every  village,  the  vast  majority  of  printing  offices  being  tiny 
enterprises  of  small  working  masters.  The  compositor, 
moreover,  has  to  deal  with  a  variety  of  employers,  from  the 
London  daily  newspaper  or  the  great  publishers'  printer, 
down  to  the  stationer's  shop  in  a  country  town  or  the  fore- 
man of  a  subsidiary  department  of  a  railway  company, 
wholesale  grocer  or  manufacturer  of  indiarubber  stamps. 
When  the  enterprising  workman  sets  up  his  hand  press  in  a 
suburban  back  street,  and  takes  a  boy  to  help  him  in  his 
jobbing  trade,  he  is  not  the  kind  of  employer  over  whom  a 
Trade  Union  can  exercise  any  effective  control.  The  Trade 
Union  does  not  even  hear  of  the  numerous  instances  in 
which  a  printing  press  is  set  up  in  the  basement  of  a  great 
advertising  manufacturer  who  chooses  to  do  his  own  printing 
on  the  premises.  In  all  such  cases  the  employment  of  boy- 
labor  is  absolutely  unrestricted  in  numbers,  and  unregulated 
by  any  educational  requirements.  The  standard  of  quality 
and  speed  of  working  is  of  the  lowest,  but  the  youth  who  in 
such  shops  picks  up  an  elementary  acquaintance  with  "  case," 
presently  gets  taken  on  as  a  cheap  "  improver  "  by  the  little 
country  stationer,  and  eventually,  whether  competent  or  not, 
drifts  to  London  to  pick  up  casual  employment  as  a 
journeyman. 

With  an  industry  pushing  out  shoots  in  this  way  into 
all  the  nooks  and  crannies  of  the  industrial  world,  it  would 
tax  the  ingenuity  of  the  most  astute  Trade  Union  official  to 
VOL.  II  2  H 


466  Trade  Union  Function 

maintain  any  effective  control  over  entrance  to  the  craft, 
Unfortunately  for  the  Compositors,  the  rules  which  their  local 
societies  have  enforced  have  actually  played  into  the  hands 
of  their  enemies.  Every  Compositors'  union  has  persistently 
striven  to  maintain  something  very  like  the  mediaeval 
apprenticeship  in  its  own  town,  quite  irrespective  of  what 
was  happening  elsewhere.  The  boy  who  would  enter  the 
printing  trade  in  Manchester  or  Newcastle  must  be  formally 
"  bound  "  to  an  employer  for  seven  years,  during  which  he 
naturally  has  to  forego  part  of  the  market  rate  of  wages. 
He  must  commence  his  service  at  an  early  age,  and  complete 
it  with  one  and  the  same  firm.  Nor  does  he  find  it  easy  to 
become  an  apprentice  at  all.  Instead  of  the  Boilermakers' 
ratio  of  two  apprentices  to  seven  journeymen,  applied  im- 
partially to  all  firms,  the  Compositors'  unions  almost  always 
impose  a  definite  maximum,  however  large  the  establishment. 
Thus,  no  printing  office  in  Glasgow  may  have  more  than  ten 
apprentices  ;  in  Leeds  none  more  than  seven  ;  in  Hull  none 
more  than  three  ;  and  in  Manchester,  "  in  order  to  adjust  the 
balance  of  supply  and  demand,  and  maintain  a  fair  remu- 
neration of  labor,  the  maximum  number  of  apprentices  in 
each  recognised  office  shall  be  three  for  the  composing  room 
and  two  for  the  machine  room."  l  Thus,  the  great  printing 
establishment  of  the  Manchester  Guardian,  employing  over  a 
hundred  compositors,  is  allowed  to  take  no  more  apprentices 
than  the  jobbing  master  with  a  dozen  men.2 

This    lopsided   limitation  has   had   a   most   unexpected 

1  Rules   of  the   Manchester    Typographical  Society  ("  instituted    November 
!797")>  Manchester,  1892,  p.  35. 

2  The    rules    of    the    compositors'    unions    generally    prescribe    a    ratio    of 
apprentices  to  journeymen,  which,  in  the  case  of  small  masters,  is  liberal.      The 
Manchester  Typographical  Society,  for  instance,  allows  a  small  master,  having 
only  two  journeymen,  to  take  a  couple  of  apprentices.      But,  unlike  the  apprentice- 
ship regulations  in  other  trades,  this  ratio  is  not  applied  to  the  large  establish- 
ments, which  are  subject   to  a  definite  maximum,  far  below  the  number  that 
the  ratio  would  allow.      How  severely  this  maximum  limits  the  total  number  of 
apprentices  in  the  best  Manchester  firms  may  be  judged  from  the  fact  that  twelve 
of  its  printing  establishments  employ  half  the  compositors  in  the  city,   having 
between  them  1000  men,  and  being  entitled  according  to  the  rule  to  only  sixty 
apprentices. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  467 

result.  It  might  be  imagined  that  Trade  Union  statesman- 
ship would  aim  at  recruiting  the  trade  from  boys  brought 
up  in  the  large  establishments,  affording  systematic  training 
in  every  branch  of  the  craft,  and  pervaded,  as  they  usually 
are,  by  a  strong  Trade  Union  feeling.1  But  the  aggregate 
number  of  apprentices  allowed  to  such  firms  is  grotesquely 
insufficient  to  maintain  the  trade.  When  new  journeymen 
are  wanted,  they  have,  in  three  cases  out  of  four,  to  be  drawn 
from  the  small  establishments,  and  ultimately  from  the  small 
towns  and  rural  districts  in  which  neither  Trade  Unionism 
nor  apprenticeship  can  be  said  to  exist.  Here  there  is 
nothing  to  prevent  an  unscrupulous  employer  from  taking 
on  as  many  boys  as  he  chooses,  keeping  them  to  the  most 
elementary  processes  of  the  craft,  and  turning  them  adrift  in 
an  untrained  state  as  soon  as  they  begin  to  ask  journeyman's 
wages.  The  direct  result  of  the  Compositors'  "  maximum  " 
of  apprentices  in  the  large  establishments  of  the  strong  Trade 
Union  towns  is,  accordingly,  to  use,  as  the  chief  breeding 
ground  and  recruiting  ground  of  the  craft,  exactly  those 
shops  and  those  districts  in  which  there  is  the  least  likeli- 
hood of  the  boys  receiving  any  proper  training.  Hence  we 
arrive  at  the  paradoxical  conclusion  that  it  is  the  very 
maintenance  of  these  apprenticeship  regulations  by  the  local 
Compositors'  unions  that  has  made  the  trade  now  practically 
an  "  open  "  one.  As  in  the  country  districts  any  number  of 
boys  are,  in  fact,  learning  to  be  compositors,  and  eventually 
drifting  into  the  towns,  the  unions  are  in  a  dilemma.  If 
they  rigidly  maintain  their  apprenticeship  rules,  and  decline 
to  admit  these  "  illegal  men,"  they  find  themselves  foiled  in 
their  negotiations  with  the  employers  by  the  presence  of  a 
steadily  growing  crowd  of  non-union  men,  indisposed  to 

1  It  is  interesting  to  note  that  there  is  at  least  one  instance  of  a  Trade  Union 
which  consciously  adopts  this  more  enlightened  policy.  The  Manchester  Union 
of  Upholsterers  (now  the  Manchester  Branch  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Upholsterers)  has  a  by-law  for  the  regulation  of  apprentices  which  limits  the 
number  of  lads  in  small  shops  and  those  doing  only  the  cheap  common  kinds  of 
work  to  one  to  six  men,  while  the  large  shops  and  those  doing  high-class  work 
are  allowed  one  to  three  men. 


468  Trade  Union  Function 

defer  to  an  organisation  from  which  they  are  excluded.  In 
order  to  gain  any  effective  power  of  Collective  Bargaining, 
the  union  must  make  up  its  mind  to  admit  practically  all  the 
men  who.  are  actually  working  at  the  trade  in  the  particular 
district,  whether  they  have  been  apprenticed  or  not.  Nearly 
all  the  local  Compositors'  unions  have  had  periodically  thus 
to  "  open  their  books,"  and  take  in  the  "  illegal  men."  And 
the  London  Society  of  Compositors,  which  includes  a  third 
of  the  Trade  Unionist  compositors  in  the  United  Kingdom, 
has,  since  1879,  avowedly  admitted  to  membership  any 
compositor  who  actually  obtains  employment  in  a  "  fair 
house"  in  London,  whether  he  has  learnt  the  trade  by 
apprenticeship  or  not.1  The  provincial  societies  still  usually 
profess  to  confine  their  membership  to  men  who  can  produce 
evidence  of  having  served  a  seven  years'  term,  but  as  they 
all  admit  without  demur  any  printer  who  gets  employment 
in  the  town  with  a  card  of  membership  of  any  other  Com- 
positors' union,  including  the  large  open  society  of  the 
Metropolis,  any  journeyman  whom  an  employer  will  engage 
on  the  standard  piece  scale  finds  no  difficulty,  whether  he  has 
been  apprenticed  or  not,  in  becoming  a  fully  recognised 
member  of  the  trade.  In  short,  what  is  limited  is,  not  the 
total  number  of  recruits  to  the  trade  in  the  kingdom  as  a 
whole,  but  the  proportion  of  such  recruits  who  receive  the 
educational  advantages  of  the  apprenticeship  system. 

The  experience  of  the  Engineers  has  been  no  less  in- 
structive than  that  of  the  Compositors,  though  in  another 
way.  The  local  trade  clubs  of  smiths  and  millwrights  at 
the  beginning  of  the  present  century  autocratically  excluded 
from  employment  all  men  who  could  not  produce  their 
indentures.2  Sir  William  Fairbairn  relates  how,  when  in 
1 8 1 1  he  obtained  a  situation  as  a  millwright  at  Rennie's, 

1  "  Every  compositor  working  as  a  journeyman,  overseer,  storekeeper,  reader, 
or  in  any  other  capacity  in  a  fair  house  .   .   .  shall  be  eligible  as  a  member." — 
Rules  of  the  London  Society  of  Compositors  (London,  1894),  p.  6. 

2  Clubs  of  smiths,  millwrights,  and   "mechanics"  took  a  leading  part  in  the 
prosecutions  and  petitions  of  the  1813  movement  to  enforce  the  apprenticeship 
laws. — History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  53-56. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  469 

the  foreman  told  him  that  he  could  not  start  until  he  had 
been  accepted  by  the  Trade  Union.  Failing  to  produce  duly 
attested  indentures,  he  was  refused  permission  to  work,  and 
driven  to  tramp  away  from  London  and  seek  a  situation  in 
a  non-unionist  district.1  Similar  regulations  lasted  down  to 
our  own  day.  The  Amicable  and  Brotherly  Society  of 
Journeymen  Millwrights,  a  Lancashire  Union  dating  certainly 
from  the  beginning  of  the  century,  maintained  down  to  1855 
its  old  by-laws  restricting  the  number  of  apprentices,  and 
rigidly  insisting  on  proof  of  servitude.  They  declare  that 
"  any  person  wishing  to  join,  whose  parents  have  neglected 
to  provide  him  with  a  proper  indenture,  shall  be  compelled 
to  produce  a  sworn  affidavit,  attested  by  two  respectable 
witnesses,  that  he  has  worked  at  the  trade  five,  six,  or  seven 
years,  in  a  millwright's  shop,  or  with  a  millwright  known  to 
the  trade,  as  an  *  apprentice,  and  he  shall  pay  any  sum  not 
less  than  £3  :  ios.,  or  more  than  £5,  that  a  general  meeting 
may  decide."  He  shall  be  "  proposed  by  a  free  member, 
and  if  it  afterwards  be  proved  that  he  was  not  legally  qualified 
the  said  member  shall  be  fined  £5.  Any  person  bringing  a 
doubtful  indenture  shall  be  subject  to  the  same  terms  of 
entrance." 2  The  same  conception  underlay  the  rules  of  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  for  the  first  thirty  years 
of  its  existence.  The  preface  to  the  edition  of  1864  de- 
clares that  "  if  constrained  to  make  restrictions  against  the 
admission  into  our  trade  of  those  who  have  not  earned  a  right 
by  a  probationary  servitude,  we  do  so,  knowing  that  such 

1  The  Life  of  Sir  William  Fairbairn,  edited  by  W.  Pole  (London,  1877), 
p.   89;   Trade   Unionism,  by  W.    Saunders  (London,  1878);  History  of  Trade 
Unionism,  pp.  75  and  187. 

2  Another   old   union   declared    "that   one  apprentice   be  allowed  to  five 
journeymen  ;  nevertheless  if  the  number  be  complete,  the  eldest,  or  next  eldest,  son 
of  a  millwright  be  allowed  to  work  at  the  trade  "  (Rules  of  the  Philanthropic 
Society  of  Journeymen  Millwrights,  1855).     How  far  the  high  entrance  fees  and 
rigid  requirements  were  intended  to  provide  technical  education  and  restrict  the 
actual  numbers  entering  the  trade,  and  how  far  they  were  designed  merely  to 
protect  the  hereditary  "  vested  interest  "  of  the  members'  sons,  is  unknown  to  us. 
It  is  quite  possible  that  the  millwrights,  at  the  beginning  of  this  century,  were,  in 
reality,  mainly  recruited  much  in  the  same  way  as  the  stonemasons  of  to-day  :  a 
reference  to  the  privileges  of  the  eldest  sons  of  millwrights,  in  the  preface  to  Sir 
W.  Fairbairn's  Treatise  on  Mills  and  Millwork,  seems  to  point  in  this  direction. 


470  Trade  Union  Function 

encroachments  are  productive  of  evil,  and  when  persevered 
in  unchecked,  result  in  reducing  the  condition  of  the  artisan 
to  that  of  the  unskilled  laborer,  and  confer  no  permanent 
advantage  on  those  admitted.  It  is  our  duty,  then,  to 
exercise  the  same  care  and  watchfulness  over  that  in  which 
we  have  a  vested  interest,  as  the  physician  does  who  holds 
a  diploma,  or  the  author  who  is  protected  by  a  copy- 
right." l  And  yet  to-day  we  find  the  Amalgamated  Society 
of  Engineers,  and  nearly  all  its  sectional  rivals,  freely  admit- 
ting to  membership  any  man,  whether  apprenticed  or  not, 
who  has  worked  for  five  years  in  an  engineering  establish- 
ment, even  if  merely  as  a  boy  or  as  a  machine  minder,  and 
who,  at  the  time  of  his  candidature,  is  obtaining  the  Standard 
Rate  of  wages  for  his  particular  branch  of  the  trade. 

This  complete  collapse  of  the  apprenticeship  regulations 
among  the  Engineers  has  not,  we  think,  been  due  to  any 
unreasonableness  in  the  regulations  themselves.  Unlike  the 
Compositors,  the  Engineers  have  never  sought  to  impose  an 
absolute  maximum  limit  of  apprentices,  or  in  any  way  to  dis- 
courage the  instruction  of  a  proportionate  number  of  boys  by 
the  large  firms.  What  they  have  aimed  at  in  their  rules  and 
in  their  negotiations  with  employers,  has  been  some  such 
arrangement  as  that  now  universally  accepted  by  the  iron- 
shipbuilders.  But,  less  fortunate  than  the  United  Society  of 
Boilermakers,  the  Engineers  have  found  their  efforts  brought 
to  nought  by  a  progressive  disintegration  of  their  old  handi- 
craft. We  have  here,  in  fact,  the  typical  case  of  the  break- 
down of  apprenticeship  under  the  influence  of  the  Industrial 
Revolution.  "  The  millwright  of  the  last  century,"  says  Sir 
William  Fairbairn,  "  was  an  itinerant  engineer  and  mechanic 
of  high  reputation.  He  could  handle  the  axe,  the  hammer, 
and  the  plane  with  equal  skill  and  precision  ;  he  could  turn, 
bore  or  forge  with  the  ease  and  despatch  of  one  brought  up 
to  these  trades,  and  he  could  set  out  and  cut  in  furrows  of  a 
millstone  with  an  accuracy  equal  or  superior  to  that  of  the 
miller  himself.  .  .  .  Generally  he  was  a  fair  arithmetician, 

1  Rules  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers,  etc.  (London,  1864). 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  471 

knew  something  of  geometry,  levelling,  and  mensuration,  and 
in  some  cases  possessed  a  very  competent  knowledge  of 
practical  mathematics.  He  oould  calculate  the  velocities, 
strength,  and  power  of  machines  :  could  draw  in  plan  and 
section,  and  could  construct  buildings,  conduits,  or  water- 
courses, in  all  the  forms  and  under  all  the  conditions  required 
in  his  professional  practice ;  he  could  build  bridges,  cut 
canals,  and  perform  a  variety  of  work  now  done  by  civil 
engineers."1  So  varied  a  proficiency  could  only  be 
attained  by  a  long  period  ot  educational  servitude.  The 
workshops  of  a  great  engineering  firm  of  to-day  present  us 
with  an  entirely  different  spectacle.  What  the  millwright 
formerly  executed  with  the  hammer  and  the  file  is  now 
broken  up  into  innumerable  separate  operations,  each  of 
which  has  its  appropriate  machine.  But  this  is  not  all.  A 
distinctive  feature  of  the  introduction  of  machinery  into  the 
engineering  trade  is  the  remarkable  variety  and  diversity  of 
the  "  power-moved  tools  "  now  required  in  a  large  machine 
shop.  A  gigantic  cotton  mill  often  contains  only  row  after 
row  of  a  single  type  of  self-acting  mule  or  power  loom.  An 
engineering  establishment  will  have  in  use  a  long  array  of 
different  types  of  drilling,  planing,  boring,  slotting,  and 
milling  machines,  together  with  a  bewildering  variety  of 
applications  of  the  old-fashioned  lathe.  The  precise  degree 
of  skill  and  trustworthiness  required  to  work  each  of  these 
machines,  or  even  to  execute  different  jobs  upon  one  of 
them,  is  infinitely  varied.  The  simple  drilling  machine  or 
the  automatic  lathe  continuously  turning  out  identical  copies 
of  some  minute  portion  of  an  engine  can  be  tended  by  a 
mere  boy.  Some  work  executed  on  an  elaborate  milling 
machine,  on  the  other  hand,  taxes  the  powers  of  the  most 
accomplished  mechanic.  Yet  so  numerous  are  the  inter- 
mediate types  that  the  increase  in  difficulty  from  each 
machine  to  the  next  is  comparatively  small.  Thus  the 
youth  or  the  laborer  who  begins  by  spending  his  whole  day 

1  A   Treatise  on  Mills  and  Milhuork,  by  Sir  William   Fairbairn  (London, 
1 86 1),  preface. 


472 


Trade  Union  Function 


in  "  minding "  the  simplest  driller  or  automatic  lathe,  may 
"  progress "  from  one  process  to  another  with  little  further 
instruction,  until,  by  mere  practice  on  a  succession  of 
machines,  the  sharp  boy  becomes  insensibly  a  qualified 
turner  or  fitter.  We  need  not  here  discuss  whether  this 
"  progression  "  of  the  more  intelligent  boys  and  laborers  is 
not  accompanied  by  the  drawback  that  the  majority,  from 
lack  of  deliberate  technical  instruction,  remain  all  their  lives 
incapable  of  any  but  the  simplest  routine  work.  Nor  need 
we  dispute  the  assertion  often  made  that  such  a  "progression" 
fails,  even  with  the  clever  and  ambitious,  to  produce  an  all- 
round  proficiency  in  mechanical  engineering.  The  fact 
remains  that  an  ever-increasing  number  of  boys  and  laborers 
do  climb  up  this  ladder,  and  become  sufficiently  competent 
to  obtain  employment  as  fitters,  turners,  and  erectors. 

The  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  has,  therefore, 
during  a  whole  generation,  been  in  a  dilemma.  Its  traditional 
policy  was  to  exclude  the  unapprenticed  interlopers  as 
"  illegal  men,"  and  this,  on  the  whole,  was  the  tendency  down 
to  1885.  But  it  found  itself  powerless  to  prevent  progression 
within  the  trade,  or  to  draw  a  line  at  any  particular  machine, 
in  order  effectively  to  separate  into  distinct  classes  the 
"machine-minders"  who  were  "engineers"  from  those  who 
were  "  laborers."  A  Trade  Union  may  conceivably 
strengthen  its  position  if,  by  limiting  the  number  of  persons 
learning  the  trade,  it  restricts  the  number  of  competitors  for 
its  particular  kind  of  employment.  But  once  those  com- 
petitors exist,  their  presence  on  the  market  as  non-unionists 
is  fatal  to  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining.  Hence  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  has  had  to  recognise 
facts  and  abandon  regulations  which  were  being  so  exten- 
sively evaded.  For  the  last  ten  years  each  successive 
delegate  meeting  has  opened  the  society  to  new  classes  of 
workmen,  whether  apprenticed  or  not,  until,  as  we  have 
already  mentioned,  any  adult  man  who  actually  obtains 
employment  at  the  Standard  Rate  of  his  particular  town  and 
grade,  is,  in  practice,  welcomed  as  a  recruit. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  475 

selves.  Yet  no  part  of  the  strength  and  success  of  this  Trade 
Union  can  be  attributed  to  a  limitation  of  apprentices,  or  to 
any  monopoly_£gature  whatsoever.  The  number  of  persons 
learning-^to  be  cotton -spinners  is,  and  has  always  been 
unrestricted.  The  trade  is  usually  recruited  from  the  class 
j0f  "  piecers,"  two  of  whom  work  under  each  spinner,  and  are 
paid  by  him.1  Thus,  instead  of  the  ratio  of  two  apprentices 
to  seven  journeymen  insisted  on  by  the  Boilermakers,  or  that 
of  one  to  ten  men  maintained  by  the  Pearl  Button  Makers,  the 
Cotton-spinners  positively  encourage  as  many  as  two  to  each 
spinner,  a  ratio  which  is  approximately  ten  times  as  great  as 
is  required  to  recruit  the  trade.  Far  from  there  being  any 
scarcity  of  candidates  for  employment,  the  great  majority  of 
piecers  have  to  abandon  all  hope  of  getting  mules,  and  find 
themselves  compelled  to  turn  to  other  occupations.  Nor  is 
any  definite  period  of  service  insisted  upon.  Any  man  may 
become  a  spinner  as  soon  as  he  can  induce  an  employer  to 
trust  him  with  a  pair  of  mules,  and  to  pay  him  for  his  product 
according  to  the  standard  list  of  piece-work  prices.2  The 
fact  that  under  these  circumstances  the  Standard  Rate  of  a 
cotton-spinner  has  been  kept  up  for  a  whole  generation,  and 
that  his  average  earnings  have  positively  increased,  may  be 
for  the  moment  left  as  an  economic  problem  to  those  who 
still  retain  the  old  belief  that  the  limitation  of  numbers  and 
the  exclusion  of  competitors  is  a  necessary  part  of  efficient 
Trade  Unionism.3 

1  Occasionally  the  employer  has  tried  to  have  only  one  boy-piecer  to  two 
spinners.     This  system,  called  "joining"  or  "partnering,"  is  always  resisted  by 
the  union,  which  insists  on  each  spinner  having  two  piecers  under  him,  on  the 
ground   that  any  other  arrangement   must  necessarily  involve   a  diminution  of 
spinners'  earnings.     The  delegate  meeting  of  the  Amalgamated  Association  of 
Operative  Cotton -spinners   in  December    1878    resolved    "that    this    meeting 
greatly  deplores  the  system  of  joining,  and  pledges  itself  to  use  every  effort  to  get 
that  system  abolished."     Since  that  date,  at  the  cost  of  many  small  strikes,  the 
Lancashire  operatives  have  gained  their  point,  and  have  now  each  two  piecers, 

2  Once  in  the  trade,  he  is  required  to  join  the  Trade  Union,  but  no  impediment 
is  placed  in  his  way. 

3  The  London  Plumbers  present  an  interesting  case,  economically  similar  in 
this  respect  to  the  Cotton-spinners.     The  employers  in  London  do  not  engage 
boys  or  apprentices  to  assist  the  men  in  plumbing,  or  to  learn  the  trade.      The 
custom  is  for  each  plumber  to  be  attended  by  an  adult  laborer,  known  as  the 


476  Trade  Union  Function 

Thus,  notwithstanding  a  strong  Trade  Union  feeling  in 
favor  of  apprenticeship  regulations,  these  cannot  be  said  to 
be  enforced  to-day  over  more  than  a  small  fraction  of  the 
Trade  Union  world,  and,  with  the  remarkable  exception  of 
the  Boilermakers,  even  this  fraction  is  steadily  dwindling.  It 
is  especially  in  such  industrial  backwaters  as  Dublin  and  Cork  ; 
in  such  homes  of  the  small-master  system  as  Sheffield  and 
Birmingham  ;  and  in  such  old-fashioned  handicrafts  as  glass- 
blowing  and  hat -making,  that  the  archaic  apprenticeship 
regulations  linger.  Over  by  far  the  largest  part  of  the 
limited  field  in  which  apprenticeship  once  prevailed,  the 
system  has  gone  practically  out  of  use,  and  restrictive  barriers, 
once  supported  by  universal  approval,  and  fondly  kept  up  by 
the  trade  clubs  of  the  eighteenth  century,  have,  during  the 
past  hundred  years,  gradually  been  swept  away.  Finally, 
so  far  from  apprenticeship  regulations  forming  a  necessary 
part  of  Trade  Unionism,  a  positive  majority  of  the  Trade 
Unionists  now  belong  to  occupations  in  which  no  shadow  of 
apprenticeship  has  ever  existed. 

To  explain  this  state  of  affairs,  we  must  distinguish 
between  the  disuse  of  apprenticeship  as  an  educational  system, 
and  its  failure  as  a  method  of  restricting  the  entrance  into  a 
craft.  The  abandonment  of  apprenticeship  as  a  form  of 
technical  training  is  not  due  to  the  discovery  of  any  satis- 
factory alternative.  There  is,  on  the  contrary,  a  remarkable 
consensus  of  opinion  among  "  practical  men,"  that  the  present 
state  of  things  is  highly  unsatisfactory.  But  many  economic 
causes  have  contributed  to  make  obsolete  the  definite  period 
of  educational  servitude  at  wages  below  the  market  value 
of  the  boy's  time.  Whatever  might  be  the  ultimate  effect 
on  the  welfare  of  the  trade  or  the  future  of  the  boy,  this 
educational  servitude  does  not  now  immediately  remunerate 

"plumber's  mate."  Any  employer  is  at  liberty  to  promote  a  plumber's  mate  to 
be  a  plumber  whenever  he  chooses,  provided  only  that  he  pays  him  the  plumber's 
Standard  Rate.  Notwithstanding  the  fact  that  the  number  of  "  plumber's  mates," 
who  form  the  class  of  learners,  is  four  or  five  times  as  numerous  as  would  suffice 
to  recruit  the  trade,  the  London  branches  of  the  United  Operative  Plumbers' 
Society  effectively  maintain  a  high  Standard  Rate. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  477 

any  of  the  parties  concerned.  The  employer  with  a  large 
establishment  does  not  care  to  be  bothered  with  boys  if  he 
has  to  teach  them  the  whole  trade.  Even  if  the  thrifty 
father  offers  £20  or  ^30  as  a  premium,  this  is  no  temptation 
to  the  capitalist  of  our  own  day,  paying  hundreds  of  pounds 
a  week  in  wages  alone.  He  prefers  to  divide  his  processes 
into  men's  work  and  boys'  work,  and  to  keep  each  grade 
permanently  to  its  allotted  routine.  Now  that  it  is  no 
longer  possible  for  the  apprentice  to  enter  his  master's  house- 
hold, and  all  gild  discipline  has  been  abolished,  the  employer 
feels  that  he  has  little  control  over  a  boy  whom  he  is  legally 
bound  to  keep  for  the  stated  term.  "  The  advantage,"  as  a 
great  builder  remarked  to  us,  "  is  all  on  the  side  of  the 
apprentice."  But  the  boy  does  not  think  so.  There  are 
to-day  so  many  opportunities  for  boys  to  earn  relatively 
high  wages  without  instruction,  that  they  are  not  easily 
induced  either  to  enter  upon  a  term  of  educational  servitude 
at  low  rates,  or  to  continue  on  it  if  they  have  begun.  "  The 
anxiety  of  the  boy  to  obtain  full  money  as  soon  as  possible 
is  largely  responsible,"  we  are  told,  "  for  the  absence  of 
apprentices."  The  father,  too,  is  naturally  tempted  to  let 
his  son  earn  six  to  fifteen  shillings  a  week  either  as  a  tele- 
graph messenger  or  errand  boy,  or  as  porter  in  some  factory 
or  workshop,  rather  than  forego  most  of  this  supplement 
to  the  family  income  in  order  merely  that  his  son  may  be 
called  an  apprentice  instead  of  a  boy. 

But  it  would  be  unfair  to  attribute  this  disinclination 
to  apprenticeship  merely  to  a  dislike  to  sacrifice  present 
income  to  future  advantage.  In  the  industrial  organisation 
of  to-day,  the  workman  finds  it  very  difficult,  if  not  in  some 
cases  impossible,  to  place  his  boy  in  any  occupation  in  which 
he  will  be  taught  a  skilled  trade.  Even  when  he  can 
apprentice  him,  he  has  little  security  that  the  boy's  instruction 
will  be  attended  to.  And  if  we  pass  from  the  individual 
father  to  the  members  of  the  craft  in  their  corporate  capacity, 
we  shall  see  that  the  system  of  apprenticeship  has  lost  what 
was  really  its  main  attraction.  "  No  one,"  said  Blackstone, 


478  Trade  Union  Function 

"  would  be  induced  to  undergo  a  seven  years'  servitude, 
if  others,  though  equally  skilful,  were  allowed  the  same 
advantages  without  having  undergone  the  same  discipline." 
What  the  father  and  the  apprentice  were  willing  to  pay  for 
was,  not  the  instruction,  but  the  legal  right  to  exercise  a 
protected  trade.  When  this  right  to  a  trade  could  be 
obtained  without  apprenticeship,  as,  for  instance,  by  way  of 
"  patrimony,"  father  and  sons  alike  have  always  been  eager 
to  forego  its  educational  advantages.  Whenever  a  Trade 
Union  has  failed  to  maintain  an  effective  limitation  of 
numbers,  it  very  soon  gives  up  striving  after  any  educational 
servitude.1 

In  certain  exceptional  occupations,  apprenticeship  can 
still  be  made  use  of  to  regulate  the  entrance  to  the  trade. 
Where  the  work  is  carried  on,  not  by  individual  craftsmen, 
but  by  associated  groups  of  highly  skilled  wage-earners,  it  is 
practically  within  the  power  of  these  groups,  if  supported 
by  the  public  opinion  of  their  own  community,  to  exclude 
any  newcomer  from  admission.  This  "  group-system  "  goes 
far,  we  think,  to  account  for  the  exceptional  effectiveness  of 
the  Trade  Union  regulations  on  apprenticeship  among  the 
Boilermakers,  Flint  Glass  Makers,  Glass  Bottle  Makers,  and 
Stuff  Pressers.  If  the  trade_  concernedconstitutes  by  itself 
only  a  tiny  but '  indispensable  fraction~~BT~artaTge  industry, 
it  will  not  be  worth  the  employer's  while  to  object  to  even 
unreasonable  demands,  so  long  as  the  Trade  Union  takes 
care  to  fill  each  Vacancy  as  it  occurs,  and  ensures  him  against 
any  interruption  of  work.  The  proprietor  of  a  cotton  mill 
is  comparatively  indifferent  to  the  restrictive  rules  insisted 
on  by  the  Tapesizers,  the.  Beamers,  Twisters,  and  Drawers, 

1  It  will  be  noticed  that,  as  among  the  various  forms  of  apprenticeship  that 
we  have  described,  the  actual  educational  advantages  vary  roughly  in  proportion 
to  the  actual  exclusiveness.  The  "  patrimony  "  of  the  Sheffield  trades  and  Stone- 
masons involves  practically  little  limitation  of  numbers,  and  offers,  on  the  other 
hand,  the  very  minimum  of  security  for  technical  instruction.  The  real  limitations 
of  the  Boilermakers  and  Flint  Glass  Makers,  on  the  contrary,  whilst  they  result 
in  something  like  a  craft  monopoly,  do  give  the  community  in  return  a  genuine 
educational  servitude,  and  provide  for  the  constant  "selection  of  the  fittest"  boys 
by  the  employers. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  479 

and  even  the  Overlookers,  whose  wages  form  but  a  trifling 
percentage  of  the  total  cost  of  production.1  It  is  only  in  the 
industries  in-  which,  by  exception,  one  or  other  of  these  con- 
ditions prevails,  that  we  see  maintained  or  revived  any 
effective  Trade  Union  limitation  of  apprenticeship.  Over 
all  the  rest  of  the  industrial  field  the  barrier  is  broken  down 
by  the  stronger  forces  of  the  mobility  of  capital,  and  the 
perpetual  revolutionising  of  industrial  processes.2  No  Trade 
Union  has  been  really  able  to  enforce  a  limitation  of  appren- 
tices if  new  employers  are  always  starting  up  in  fresh  centres  ; 
if  the  craft  is  frequently  being  changed  by  the  introduction 
of  new  processes  or  machinery ;  if  alternative  classes  of 
workers  can  be  brought  in  to  execute  some  portion  of  the 
operation.  These  are  precisely  the  conditions  which  are 
typical  of  most  of  the  industries  of  the  present  century. 

Trade  Unions  might,  it  is  true,  appeal  to  the  law.  But 
apart  from  the  insuperable  difficulties  of  adapting  any  legally 
enforced  apprenticeship  to  the  circumstances  of  modern 
industry,  it  is  easy  to  see  that  no  revival  of  the  system  would 
gain  the  support  of  public  opinion.  From  the  point  of  view 
of  the  community  the  old  system  has  three  capital  disadvan- 
tages. There  is  no  security  to  the  public  that  the  appren- 
tice will  be  thoroughly  and  efficiently  taught.  It  is  no 
longer  the  "  master  craftsman "  who  himself  instructs  the 
boy  and  has  a  direct  pecuniary  interest  in  his  early  pro- 
ficiency. The  scores  of  apprentices  in  a  modern  shipyard 

1  It  is  to  this  consideration,  we  think,  that  the  Patternmakers  in  engineering 
establishments,    and   the   Lithographic  Printers  in   the  great   firms  which   now 
dominate  that  trade,  owe  their  relatively  effective  position  as  regards  apprentice- 
ship. 

2  The  sawyers  exhibit  a  curious  evolution.      The  old  hand  sawyers  of  the 
early  part  of  the  century  were  notorious  for  the  strength  and  exclusiveness  of  their 
Trade  Unions.     The  introduction  of  the  circular  saw,  driven  by  steam  power, 
led  to  the  supersession  of  the  old  handicraftsmen  by  a  new  class  of  comparatively 
unskilled  workers,  who  were  drawn  from  the  ranks  of  the  laborers,  and  remained 
for  some  years  unorganised.     With  the  increasing  speed  and  growing  complica- 
tion of  mill-sawing  machinery,  these  mill-sawyers  have,  in  their  turn,  become  a 
highly  specialised  class,  whom  an  employer  finds  some  difficulty  in  supplanting 
by  laborers.       The  comparative  stability  which  the  industry  has  now  attained 
has  enabled  these  machine  workers  to  establish  an  effective  union,  which  is  gradu- 
ally enforcing  a  fixed  period  of  apprenticeship. 

6 


480  Trade  Union  Function 

are  necessarily  left  mainly  to  learn  their  business  for  them- 
selves, by  watching  workmen  who  are  indifferent  or  even 
unfriendly  to  their  progress,  with  possibly  some  occasional 
hints  from  a  benevolent  foreman.  In  these  days  of  peda- 
gogic science,  elaborately  trained  teachers,  and  "  Her  Majesty's 
Inspectors  of  Schools,"  the  haphazard  relation  between  the 
apprentice  and  his  instructors  will  certainly  not  commend 
itself  to  the  deliberate  judgment  of  the  community.  More- 
over, all  history  indicates  that  an  apprenticeship  system  must 
leave  outside  its  scope  the  large  proportion  of  boys  who 
recruit  the  vast  army  of  unskilled  laborers.  In  the  absence 
of  an  apprenticeship  system,  the  abler  and  more  energetic  of 
these  succeed,  as  we  have  seen,  in  "  picking  up  "  a  trade,  and 
in  progressing,  as  adults,  according  to  their  capacities.  One 
of  the  darkest  features  of  the  whole  history  of  apprenticeship 
is  the  constant  necessity,  if  the  system  is  to  be  maintained  at 
all,  of  excluding,  from  the  protected  occupations,  all  "  illegal 
men."  We  need  not  weary  the  reader  with  mediaeval  in- 
stances.1 But  it  will  be  obvious  that  the  elaborate  Appren- 
ticeship Treaty  concluded  between  the  Boilermakers  and  their 

1  It  is  usually  forgotten  that  gild  membership,  and  the  right  to  carry  on  a 
skilled  craft,  at  no  time  extended  to  the  great  army  of  laborers.  The  case  of  the 
Bladesmiths  may  serve  to  remind  us  of  the  existence  of  a  vast  mass  of  unappren- 
ticed  workers.  On  the  loth  October  1408  the  masters  of  the  trade  of  the 
"  Blaydesmiths  "  in  London  presented  a  petition  and  a  code  of  articles  for  the 
government  of  the  trade  to  the  Mayor  and  Corporation.  These  articles  were 
read  and  approved,  and  they  include  one,  "That  no  one  of  the  said  trade  shall 
teach  his  journeymen  the  secrets  of  his  trade  as  he  would  his  apprentice,  on  the 
pain  aforesaid  "  (namely  a  fine  of  6s.  8d.  for  the  first  offence,  los.  for  the  second, 
and  133.  4d.  for  any  further  offence).  The  journeymen  alluded  to  here  were  no 
doubt  the  "  strikers"  who  assisted  the  smiths  in  their  task. — See  Riley's  Memo- 
rials of  London  and  London  Life  (London,  1868),  p.  570. 

How  large  was  the  proportion  of  unapprenticed  laborers  is  perhaps  roughly 
indicated  by  the  fire  regulations  of  the  Common  Council  of  London  in  1667, 
when  the  "  handicraft  companies  "  of  Carpenters,  Bricklayers,  Plasterers,  Painters, 
Masons,  Smiths,  Plumbers  and  Paviours  were  ordered  to  elect  yearly  for  each 
company,  2  Master  Workmen,  4  Journeymen,  8  Apprentices  and  16  Laborers  to 
form  a  Fire  Brigade  (Jupp,  History  of  the  Carpenter?  Company,  London,  p.  284). 
There  are  many  occupations  to-day  in  which  the  number  of  unskilled  laborers 
exceeds  that  of  the  skilled  craftsmen  ;  and  it  may  well  be  that  the  gilds  at  no 
time  included  more  than  a  minority  even  of  the  adult  male  workers. — See  His- 
tory of  Trade  Unionism ,  p.  37 ;  Du  Cellier,  Histoire  des  Classes  Laborieuses  en  France 
(Paris,  1860),  p.  204;  Mrs.  Green,  Town  Life  in  Fifteenth  Centtiry,  ii.  103. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  481 

employers  necessarily  closes  the  door  of  advancement  to  the 
crowd  of  rivet-boys  and  platers'  helpers  in  an  iron-shipyard, 
some  of  whom  would  otherwise  find  themselves  able  to  pick 
up  the  trade.  The  Carpet-weavers  are  driven  to  prohibit 
any  person,  other  than  a  "  registered  creeler  "  (the  apprentice), 
"  to  be  at  the  front  of  the  loom  or  otherwise  doing  the  work 
of  the  weaver,"  l  lest  he  should  insidiously  learn  the  art.  The 
Calico-printers  absolutely  forbid  their  "  tenters,"  or  laborers, 
ever  to  touch  the  "  doctor "  (the  long  knife  which  adjusts 
the  precise  amount  of  coloring  matter),  or  even  to  come  in 
front  of  the  machine.  Unless  a  sharp  line  is  drawn,  either 
by  law  or  by  custom,  between  duly  apprenticed  craftsmen 
and  "  illegal  men,"  it  is  obvious  that  no  apprenticeship  system 
can  long  exist.  Finally,  when  such  a  separate  class  is 
created,  the  community  can  never  tell  to  what  extent  it  is 
being  mulcted  for  the  maintenance  of  the  system.  It  was, 
in  fact,  the  cost  to  the  community,  and,  as  he  thought,  the 
excessive  cost,  that  led  Adam  Smith  so  fervently  to  denounce 
the  whole  apprenticeship  system,  with  its  inevitable  conse- 
quences of  monopoly  wages  and  profits.  In  our  own  day, 
it  is  impossible  to  calculate  how  much  it  costs  the  community 
to  educate  a  boilermaker  or  glassblower.  We  may  infer 
that  we  are  paying  for  it  in  the  relatively  high  wages  of  these 
protected  trades,  but  how  much  we  are  paying  in  this  way, 
and  upon  whom  this  burden  is  falling,  it  is  impossible  to 
compute.  Undemocratic  in  its  scope,  unscientific  in  its 
educational  methods,  and  fundamentally  unsound  in  its 
financial  aspects,  the  apprenticeship  system,  in  spite  of  all 
the  practical  arguments  in  its  favor,  is  not  likely  to  be 
deliberately  revived  by  a  modern  democracy.2 

1  Rules  of  the  Power  Loom  Carpet-weavers*  Mutual  Defence  and  Provident 
Association  (Kidderminster,  1891). 

2  It  may  be   inferred   that   technical   education,    even  more   than    common 
schooling,  is  too  immediately  costly,  if  not  also  too  remote  in  its  advantages,  to 
be  within  the  means  of  the  great  majority  of  parents.     Individual  capitalists,  who 
are  not  necessarily  interested  in  the  future  welfare  even  of  their  own  trades,  will 
not  bear  the  expense  of  teaching  a  new  generation  of  skilled  workmen — whom 
they  may  never  need  to  employ.     Thus,   though   Mr.    Inglis   strongly  objected 
to  any  limitation  of  the  number  of  apprentices,  he  explains  why  he  and  other 

VOL.  II  21 


482  Trade  Union  Function 


(]}}  The  Limitation  of  Boy -Lab  or 

The  abandonment  of  the  old  period  of  educational  servi- 
tude has,  in  some  instances,  created  a  new  problem.  When 
the  employer  finds  himself  freed  from  all  obligation  to  teach 
his  boys,  and  is,  on  the  other  hand,  obliged  to  pay  them  the 
full  market  value  of  their  time,  he  naturally  prefers  to  keep 
them  continuously  employed  on  such  routine  work  as  they 
can  best  perform.  The  manufacturing  process  is  therefore 
subdivided,  so  that  as  large  a  portion  as  possible  shall  fall 
within  the  competence  of  boys  kept  exclusively  to  one 
particular  task.  From  the  point  of  the  Trade  Union,  this 
constitutes  a  new  grievance.  It  is  no  longer  a  case  of 
objecting  to  an  undue  multiplication  of  apprentices,  leading  in 
course  of  time  to  an  unnecessary  increase  in  the  number  of 
competent  workmen  seeking  employment.  What  the  men 
complain  of  is  that  the  employers  are  endeavouring,  by  an 
alteration  of  the  manufacturing  process,  to  dispense  with 
skilled  labor,  or,  indeed,  with  adult  labor  altogether.  So  far 
this  complaint  may  appear  only  another  instance  of  "  New 
Processes  and  Machinery,"  a  subject  sufficiently  dealt  with  in 
a  preceding  chapter.  If  the  employer,  by  any  change  of 
process,  can  bring  his  work  within  the  capacity  of  operatives 
of  a  lower  grade  of  strength  or  skill,  it  is  useless,  as  we  have 
seen,  for  the  superior  workers  who  were  formerly  employed 
to  resist  the  change.  When,  however,  the  innovation  involves, 
not  the  substitution  of  one  class  of  adults  for  another,  but  of 
boys  for  men,  a  new  argument  has  to  be  considered.  To 
the  grown-up  workmen  in  a  trade,  it  seems  preposterous  that 
they  should  be  thrown  out  of  employment  by  their  youthful 
sons  being  taken  on  in  their  places.  Their  aggravation  is 

employers  agreed  to  the  Trade  Union  restriction.  "We  have,"  he  says,  "oui 
business  proper  to  attend  to,  and  cannot  devote  all  our  energies  to  striving  for 
the  greatest  good  of  the  greatest  number"  (The  Apprentice  Question,  p.  10). 
If  the  community  desires  to  see  a  constant  succession  of  skilled  craftsmen,  the 
community  as  a  whole  will  have  to  pay  for  their  instruction.  Even  with  an 
apprenticeship  system,  the  community,  as  we  suggest  above,  really  paid  in  the 
long  run. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  483 

increased  when  they  see  these  sons,  not  taught  any 
skilled  craft,  but  kept,  year  after  year,  at  the  simplest  routine 
work,  and  discharged  in  favor  of  their  younger  brothers 
as  soon  as  they  begin  to  ask  the  ordinary  wage  of  an  adult 
laborer. 

To  prevent  this  evil,  some  Trade  Unions,  which  have 
given  up  the  requirement  of  a  period  of  educational  servitude, 
have  attempted  to  enforce  a  simple  limitation  of  boy-labor. 
They  may  make  no  objection  to  any  number  of  boys  being 
properly  taught  their  craft,  and  so  rendered  competent 
workmen.  Such  apprentices  would  naturally  be  put  first 
to  the  simpler  processes.  But  when  these  simpler  tasks  are 
permanently  separated  from  the  rest,  and  handed  over  to  a 
distinct  race  of  boys,  who  are  not  intended  to  learn  the 
remainder  of  the  work  ;  when  the  number  of  boys  so  employed 
is  steadily  increased,  and  the  number  of  adult  workmen 
diminished,  the  change  is  always  fiercely  resisted  by  the 
Trade  Union.  We  need  only  describe  the  leading  instance, 
that  of  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives. 
Here  the  substitution  of  boys  for  men  has  been  hotly  con- 
tested for  many  years.  At  first  the  union  sought  to  meet 
the  case  by  enforcing  the  usual  apprenticeship  regulations. 
But  with  the  growing  use  of  machinery  and  subdivision  of 
labor,  "  any  attempt  to  restrict  the  entrance  by  making  the 
conditions  not  so  profitable  at  first — by  making  the  wage 
small  and  the  years  long  "  J — was  broken  down  by  the  fact 
that  boys,  taking  short  views  of  their  own  advantage, 
preferred  to  earn  the  relatively  higher  wages  of  unapprenticed 
machine-minders.  This  led,  as  one  of  the  men's  spokesmen 
declared  in  1892,  to  "the  wholesale  flooding  of  the  market 
with  boys,  and  the  wholesale  discharging  of  men.  ...  I 
have  proof  before  me  of  where  a  number  of  fathers  in  this 
town  (Leicester)  have  been  discharged,  and  their  sons  set  on 
in  their  places.  .  .  .  We  have  firms  to-day — though  we  ask 
for  the  limitation  of  I  boy  to  5  men — we  have  firms  in 
Leicester  where  they  have  5  men  to  6  boys,  19  men  to 

1  National  Conference,  1893  ;  proceedings  before  Umpire. 


484  Trade  Union  Function 

1 4  boys,  2  3  men  to  1 1  boys,  5  men  to  2 1  boys,  i  3  men  to 
I  8  boys,  6  men  to  4  boys,  3  men  to  9  boys,  and  3  men  to 
i  boy."  l  The  men  complained  that  this  state  of  things  not 
only  deprived  them  of  employment,  but  that  it  also  prevented 
those  who  were  employed  from  getting  the  Standard  Rate. 
"In  the  town  I  come  from  (Norwich),"  said  another  re- 
presentative, "  it  is  all  very  well  for  employers  to  say,  '  I 
will  pay  a  certain  price  for  your  labor.'  But  the  moment  a 
man  asks  for  the  price  agreed  upon  he  is  discharged,  and  a 
boy  is  put  in  his  place." 2 

The  union  accordingly  asked  that  the  maximum  number 
of  boys  in  any  factory  should  be  fixed  at  the  ratio  of  one  to 
every  five  journeymen.  The  employers  did  not  dispute  the 
facts.  They  refused  to  discuss  whether  the  change  was  for 
the  public  advantage  or  not.  They  fell  back  on  the  simple 
position  that  the  employment  of  boys  was  a  matter  entirely 
"  within  the  province  of  the  employer,  and  that  it  is  not 
a  question  in  which  the  workmen  may  rightly  interfere." 
They  declared  that  any  limit  on  the  number  of  boys  would 
be  "  not  only  an  encroachment  on  the  right  of  manufacturers 
to  manage  their  own  business  in  their  own  way,  but  also 
it  is  impracticable,  and  cannot  be  carried  out,  because  of  the 
varying  circumstances  of  the  various  portions  of  the  trade, 
and  of  the  various  employers  and  various  towns."  3  The  issue 
was  in  due  course  remitted  to  the  umpire,  Sir  Henry  (now 
Lord)  James,  in  pursuance  of  the  collective  agreement  de- 
scribed in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Method  of  Collective  Bargain- 
ing." The  employers  used  every  argument  in  defence  of 
their  "  right "  to  carry  on  their  own  business  in  their  own 
way.  The  men's  demonstration  of  the  evils  of  this  excessive 
use  of  boy-labor  was,  however,  so  overwhelming  that  the 
umpire  felt  bound  to  admit  their  contention.  In  a  remark- 
able award,  dated  22nd  August  1892,  the  principle  of  re- 
stricting, by  Common  Rule,  the  proportion  of  boys  to  be 
employed  by  any  manufacturer  in  the  boot  and  shoe  trade 

1  National  Conference,  1893  ;  proceedings  before  Umpire,  1892,  p.  62, 
*  Ibid.  p.  63.  3  Ibid.  pp.  94,  96. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  485 

was  definitely  established,  the  ratio  being    fixed  at  one  to 
three  journeymen.1 

It  is  not  easy  to  imagine  the  feelings  with  which  Nassau 
Senior  or  Harriet  Martineau  would  have  viewed  the  spectacle 
of  an  eminent  Liberal  lawyer  imposing  such  a  restriction 
on  "  the  right  of  every  man  to  employ  the  capital  he  inherits, 
or  has  acquired,  according  to  his  own  discretion,  without 
molestation  or  obstruction,  so  long  as  he  does  not  infringe  on 
the  rights  or  property  of  others." 2  Lord  James  was  con- 
vinced that  he  had  to  cope  with  a  real  evil.  That  a  genera- 
tion of  highly-skilled  craftsmen  should  be  succeeded  by  a 
generation  incapable  of  anything  but  the  commonest  routine 
labor,  seemed  to  him  to  be  a  disadvantage,  not  only  to  the 
craftsmen  themselves,  but  also  to  the  community.  The  com- 
petition between  the  boys  and  their  fathers  is,  it  was  argued, 
an  "  unfair  "  one.3  The  wages  paid  in  a  boot  factory  to  a  boy 
between  thirteen  and  eighteen,  though  large  in  comparison 
with  those  given  to  the  old-fashioned  apprentice,  are  far 
below  the  sum  on  which  the  race  of  operatives  could  be 

1  "In  the  matter  of  an  arbitration  between  the  National  Union  of  Boot  and 
Shoe  Operatives,  and  the  National  Federation  of  Associated  Employers  of  Labor 
in  the  Shoe  Trade,  I,  the  undersigned,  having  taken  upon  myself  the  burden  of 
the  said  Arbitration,  and  having  heard  the  parties  thereto  by  themselves  and  their 
Witnesses,  do  now  in  respect  of  the  matters  in  dispute  submitted  to  me,  adjudge 
and  determine  as  follows  :   '  That  in  respect  of  the  work  carried  on  by  Clickers, 
Pressmen,   Lasters,  and  Finishers,  the  Employers  of  Labor   in  Shoe  Factories 
and  Workshops  shall  in  each  department  respectively  be  restricted  in  the  employ- 
ment of  boys  (under   18)  to  one  boy  to  every  three  men  employed.     And  that 
where  the  number  of  men  employed  shall  not  be  divisible  by  three,  one  boy  may 
also  be  employed  in  respect  of  the  fraction  existing,  either  less  than  three,  or 
above  each  unit  of  three. 

"That  whilst  the  above  restriction  is  general  in  its  prima facie  application,  I 
further  adjudge  that  it  may  be  inexpedient  in  certain  Factories  and  Workshops  in 
which  the  manufacture  of  goods  called  'Nursery  Goods,'  and  other  goods  of  a 
common  quality  and  of  a  low  price  is  carried  on."  Other  clauses  provided  for 
the  adaptation  by  the  Local  Boards  of  the  general  restriction  to  such  low-class 
firms,  and  for  the  reference  of  disputes  to  an  umpire. — National  Conference, 
1892,  p.  149. 

2  Report  of  the  Committee  on  the  State  of  the  Woollen  Manufacture  in  England, 
4th  July  1806,  p.  12;  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  p.  56. 

3  See  our  chapter  on  "New  Processes  and^Machinery,"  for  other  instances  of,  in 
this  sense,  "unfair"  competition ;  and  our  chapter  on  "The  Economic  Characteristics 
of  Trade  Unionism,"  for  fuller  consideration  of  the  results  of"  parasitic  trades." 


486  Trade  Union  Function 

permanently  maintained,  and  therefore  below  what  may  be 
called  the  boy's  cost  of  production.  An  employer  carrying 
on  his  factory  entirely  by  boy  -  labor,  and  yet  giving  the 
boys  no  educational  training,  is,  therefore,  enjoying  a  positive 
subsidy  in  aid  of  just  that  form  of  industrial  organisation 
which  is  calculated  to  be,  in  the  long  run,  the  most  injurious 
to  the  community. 

But  though  the  excessive  multiplication  of  boy  -  labor 
may  be  a  grave  social  danger,  and  though  Lord  James's 
remedy  of  limitation  is  not  without  precedent,1  we  think  that 
experience  points  to  the  impossibility  of  any  Trade  Union 
coping  with  the  evil  in  this  way.  Even  Lord  James's  award, 
with  all  its  decided  acceptance  of  the  principle  of  restriction, 
gave  away  the  men's  case  by  its  exceptions.  He  refused 
to  bind  those  employers  who  "  manufactured  goods  called 
*  Nursery  goods '  and  other  goods  of  a  common  quality 
and  of  a  low  price,"  on  the  ground  that  no  uniform  ratio  of 
boys  to  men  was  applicable  to  their  branch  of  the  trade.  In 
this  refusal  there  can  be  no  doubt  that  he  exercised  a  wise 
discretion.  To  have  insisted  on  these  "  Nursery "  manu- 
facturers doing  work  by  adult  labor  which  was  actually  being 
performed  by  boys  would  have  resulted  only  in  their 
immediate  withdrawal  from  the  Federation  of  Employers, 
and  so  from  the  scope  of  the  award.  Thus,  these  low-class 

1  We  know  of  no  other  instance  of  the  direct  limitation  of  the  number  of  boy 
workers  in  a  trade  by  the  award  of  an  arbitrator,  or  even  by  mutual  consent  of  the 
employers  and  men,  though  the  award  of  Mr.  T.  (afterwards  Judge)  Hughes  in 
the  case  of  the  Kidderminster  Carpet  Weavers  in  1875,  by  which  the  number  of 
boys  allowed  to  actually  work  on  looms  was  limited  to  one  to  five  men,  was  given 
partly  on  these  grounds  (see  Report  of  Conference  of  Manufacturers  and  Work- 
men before  T.  Hughes,  Esq.,  Q.C.,  at  .  .  .  Kidderminster,  ^oth  July  1875. 
Kidderminster  1875).  But  there  are  several  instances  of  regulations  by  Trade 
Unions  aiming  at  this  end.  Thus  in  1892  the  Brassfounders3  Society  at  Hull 
succeeded  in  enforcing  a  very  strict  limitation  of  the  number  of  boys  in  each  shop, 
in  order  to  stop  the  competition  of  excessive  boy-labor.  The  Whitesmiths  in  the 
North  of  England,  the  Coppersmiths  of  Glasgow,  and  the  Packing-case  Makers  in 
Bradford  and  other  towns  have  made  similar  efforts  to  check  the  growth  of  this 
practice,  whilst  the  Amalgamated  Wood  Turners'  Society  of  London,  in  a  circular 
to  their  employers  in  1890,  urged  that  all  lads  in  the  trade  should  be  apprenticed 
for  five  years,  "a  system  which,  when  carried  out,  would  be  as  great  a  blessing 
for  the  lad  as  for  the  master,  and  remove  the  unfair  competition  of  boy-labor." 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  487 

manufacturers,  together  with  all  small  masters  and  non- 
associated  firms,  go  on  employing  as  many  boys  as  they 
choose.  The  umpire's  award,  in  fact,  only  applied  to  those 
cases  in  which  it  was  least  required.  The  National  Union 
of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  accordingly  finds  itself  in  much 
the  same  position  with  regard  to  boy  -  labor  as  the 
Typographical  Association  does  with  regard  to  apprentices. 
It  nominally  possesses  the  power  of  limiting  the  number, 
but  this  power  is  only  effective  in  high-class  establishments, 
and  not  even  in  all  these.  The  only  result  of  enforcing 
the  limit  is  thus,  not  any  restriction  of  the  total  number 
of  boys  in  the  trade,  but  merely  their  concentration  in 
particular  districts  or  particular  establishments  from  which, 
as  they  grow  up,  they  overflow  to  the  others.  The  trade 
remains,  therefore,  as  overrun  as  ever,  with  the  added  evil 
that  it  tends  more  and  more  to  be  recruited  from  the  least 
educational  channels. 

In  other  trades  the  failure  to  put  any  effective  restriction 
on  the  employment  of  boy-labor  has  been  even  more  decided 
than  among  the  Boot  Operatives  and  the  Compositors.  The 
Engineers  and  Ironmoulders,  for  instance,  have  from  time 
to  time  attempted  to  enforce  a  limit  of  boy -labor.  Such 
regulations  can  for  a  time  be  enforced  in  strong  Trade 
Union  towns,  in  those  branches  of  the  trade  which  absolutely 
demand  skilled  workmen,  and  in  establishments  where  Trade 
Unionism  has  gained  a  firm  hold.  But  in  the  meantime  the 
boys,  even  in  Trade  Union  strongholds,  will  have  been 
crowding  into  the  workshops  of  small  masters,  or  of  those 
low-grade  establishments  which  rely  almost  exclusively  on 
boy-labor.  At  the  same  time,  as  in  the  analogous  case  of 
Trade  Union  Regulations  on  apprenticeship,  the  non-unionist 
districts  will  be  bringing  in  an  unlimited  number  of  recruits, 
who  have  grown  up  outside  Trade  Union  influence. 

It  may  be  objected  that  this  drawback  to  any  limitation 
of  boy-labor  relates,  not  to  the  regulation  itself,  but  to  the 
method  by  which  it  is  enforced.  If  instead  of  a  mere 
voluntary  agreement,  the  limitation  were  imposed  by  law, 


488  Trade  Union  Function 

its  universal  application  would,  it  may  be  argued,  effectually 
put  a  stop  to  the  abuse  that  is  complained  of.  Such  a  law 
would,  however,  have  to  be  considered  from  the  point  of  view 
of  those  whom  it  excluded  from  the  trade,  as  well  as  from 
that  of  those  whom  it  protected.  A  community  which  per- 
emptorily limited  the  number  of  boys  whom  employers  might 
engage  would  find  itself  under  an  obligation  to  provide  some 
other  means  of  maintenance  for  those  who  remained  over. 
If  the  law  attempted  to  distribute  the  annual  supply  of  boys 
proportionately  over  all  the  industries  of  the  country,  it  would 
have  to  get  over  the  difficulty,  which  Lord  James  found 
insuperable,  of  framing  any  Common  Rules  that  could  be 
applied  to  the  different  grades  of  establishments,  in  all  the 
innumerable  varieties  of  occupation — to  say  nothing  of  the 
complications  arising  from  trades  which  employ  no  boys 
at  all,  and  from  others  in  which  boys  only  are  required. 
Finally,  in  order  to  arrive  at  the  necessary  adjustment 
between  the  total  supply  of  boy-labor  and  the  demand  for 
it,  as  well  as  to  hit  off  the  happy  mean  between  undue 
laxness  and  economic  monopoly  in  any  particular  trade,  it 
would  need  to  be  based  upon  data  as  yet  absolutely  unknown, 
as  to  the  rate  at  which  each  trade  was  increasing,  and  the 
length  of  the  average  operative's  working  life.1  In  short, 
whilst  any  legal  restriction  on  the  number  of  boys  to  be 

1  See  "  The  Fair  Number  of  Apprentices  in  a  Trade,"  by  C.  P.  Sanger,  in 
Economic  Journal,  December  1895. 

The  Factories  and  Shops  Act  of  1896  (No.  1445)  of  the  Colony  of  Victoria 
empowers  (sec.  15)  a  special  Board  appointed  by  the  Governor,  and  consisting  of 
equal  numbers  of  employers  and  employed,  to  fix,  in  the  Clothing,  Bootmaking, 
Furniture,  and  Breadmaking  industries,  "  the  number  or  proportionate  number 
of  apprentices  and  improvers  under  the  age  of  eighteen  years  who  may  be  em- 
ployed within  any  factory  or  workroom,  and  the  lowest  price  or  rate  of  pay- 
payable  "  to  them.  Any  person  employing  more  than  the  number  or  proportion 
so  fixed  is  made  liable  to  fine,  and,  on  a  third  offence,  the  registration  of  his 
factory  or  workroom  "  shall  without  further  or  other  authority  than  this  Act  be 
forthwith  cancelled  by  the  Chief  Inspector."  If  this  law  is  ever  put  effectively 
in  force,  its  working  will  deserve  the  careful  attention  of  economists. 

We  should  ourselves  be  inclined  to  look  for  a  remedy  of  the  evil  of  excessive 
boy-labor,  not  to  any  Trade  Union  Regulation,  nor  yet  to  any  law  limiting  numbers, 
but  (following  the  precedent  set  with  regard  to  children's  employment)  to  a  simple 
extension  of  Factory  Act  and  educational  requirements  ;  see  our  chapter  on  "  The 
Economic  Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism." 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  489 

employed  in    a   particular  industry  can   scarcely  fail    to  be 

inequitable,    any    general  restriction     on    the    number    of 

boys  to   be   employed   in  all   trades   whatsoever   is   plainly 
impossible. 

(c)  Progression  'within  the  Trade 

We  come  now  to  a  small  but  interesting  series  of 
Trade  Union  Regulations  which  have  hitherto  escaped 
attention.  There  are  some  trades  which  are  not  recruited 
from  boys  at  all,  but  from  adult  men,  who  leave  their 
previous  work  and  "  progress  "  to  more  responsible  duties. 

TJlllSv-Jthe    T  nnrlnn     EnnHf^^jTavim^ 

employ  boys,  the  Operative  Society  of  Bricklayers  is  now 
largely  recruited,  in  the  very  numerous  Metropolitan  branches, 
from  young  builders'  laborers,  who  are  permitted  to  decide, 
up  to  the  age  of  twenty-five,  whether  they  will  permanently 
abandon  the  hod  for  the  trowel.1  In  this  case  the  pro- 
gression is  practically  ^unregulated  by  any  definite  rule. 
Elsewhere  the  arrangements  are  sometimes  more  elaborate? 
Thus,  the  ^malLJdanchester^  Slaters'  and  "Laborers'  Society 
practically  admits  to  membership,  as  a  laborer,  any  man 
who  is  actually  working  with  a  slater,  and  it  is  from  such 
laborers  that  the  ranks  of  the  slaters  are  recruited.  But 
although  the  laborers  form  a  majority  of  the  society,  the  rules 
provide  for^strjctregulation  of  this  progressjpa<  Any  slater's 
laborer  who  desires  to  become  a  slater  must  first  serve  seven 
years  in  the  lower  grade,  and  then  apply  to  the  secretary  of 
the  union.  A  committee  of  six  practical  slaters  is  then 
appointed,  by  whom  the  candidate  is  examined  in  all  the 
mysteries  of  the  art.  If  he  passes  this  ordeal,  he  is  recognised 
as  a  slater,  and  entitled  to  demand  the  full  slater's  pay.  The 
number  of  laborers  so  promoted  is  limited  to  three  in  each 
year.2 

1  It  must  be  borne  in  mind  that,  as  part  of  the  defence  of  the  Standard  Rate, 
no  laborer  is  permitted  to  do  occasional  work  as  a  bricklayer. 

2  Rules  of  the  Manchester  and  Salford  District  Slaters'  and  Laborers'  Society 
(Manchester,  1890).     The  London  plumbers,  in  the  absence  of  boy  apprentices, 


4QO  Trade  Union  Function 

A  more  complicated  system  of  progression  is  to  be  found 
in  some  trades  in  which  the  operatives  are  divided  into 
different  grades.  Among  the  Steel  Smelters  the  sub- 
ordinates, known  as  wheel-chargemen,  who  are  recruited  from 
ordinary  laborers,  perform  the  onerous  task  of  bringing  to 
the  furnace  the  heavy  loads  of  pig-iron  with  which  it  is 
charged.  The  men  actually  engaged  in  the  smelting  opera- 
tions are  divided  into  three  grades,  having  varying  degrees 
of  responsibility  for  the  successful  issue  of  this  very  costly 
process,  but  all  alike  engaged  in  severe  physical  exertion  and 
exposed  to  excessive  heat.  When  a  vacancy  occurs  in  the 
third  or  lowest  grade,  one  of  the  wheel-chargemen  is  promoted 
to  fill  it.  A  vacancy  in  any  of  the  higher  grades  must  be 
offered  first  to  any  workman  of  that  particular  grade  who 
happens  to  be  out  of  employment.  If  no  such  candidate 
appears,  it  is  then  filled  by  selection  by  the  employer  from 
the  next  lower  grade.  A  precisely  similar  arrangement  is 
combined  with  apprenticeship  among  the  Silk-dressers,  who 
are  divided  into  apprentices,  third  hands,  second  hands,  and 
first  hands.  Among  the  Flint  Glass  Makers  the  hierarchy 
of  grades  is  even  more  complex.  An  apprentice  may 
become  either  a  "  footmaker "  or  may,  if  he  is  competent, 
skip  that  grade  and  become  at  once  a  "  servitor."  But  no 
"  servitor  "  may  become  a  "  workman,"  and  no  "  footmaker  " 
a  "  servitor,"  so  long  as  any  man  in  the  higher  grade  is  out 
of  employment.1  In  the  strongly-organised  United  Society 

are,  as  we  have  already  mentioned,  assisted  by  men  known  as  "  plumbers'  mates," 
who  have  a  union  of  their  own.  An  employer  is  free  to  promote  a  plumber's 
mate  to  be  a  plumber,  whenever  he  considers  him  to  be  worth  the  plumbers' 
Standard  Rate.  In  most  parts  of  the  country  the  "  forgers "  or  smiths  in 
manufacturing  establishments  are  similarly  recruited  from  the  strikers  who  work 
in  conjunction  with  them,  and  who  are  in  the  same  union. 

1  Thus  a  Flint  Glass  Maker,  advocating  a  scheme  for  the  absorption  of  the 
unemployed,  declared  that  "  the  servitor  that  has  been  waiting  for  an  opportunity 
to  get  to  the  Workman's  chair  would  then  get  his  desire  ;  the  Footmaker  that  was 
put  to  make  foot  when  he  was  bound  apprentice,  and  is  still  in  that  position, 
although  he  may  be  thirty  years  of  age,  and  perhaps  more  than  that,  with  a  wife 
and  family  dependent,  upon  him,  and  the  reason  of  his  still  being  in  that  position 
is  not  that  he  has  not  the  ability  to  be  in  a  higher  one,  but  because  there  has  been 
no  vacancy  only  where  there  has  been  an  unemployed  man  ready  to  fill  it  and 
keep  him  back." — Letter  in  Flint  Glass  Makers'  Magazine,  November  1888. 


Entrance  to  a  Trade  491 

of  Boilermakers  this  system  of  progression  is  curiously 
worked  in  with  the  existence  of  an  inferior  grade  of  operatives, 
who  are  freely  admitted  to  the  union,  but  are  only  permitted 
to  progress  under  certain  conditions.  The  platers,  angle-iron 
smiths,  and  rivetters  who  form  the  bulk  of  the  society  are 
mostly  recruited  under  the  strictly-regulated  apprenticeship 
system  which  we  have  described.  But  there  is  also  another 
class  of  members,  called  "  holders  up,"  who  are  less  skilled 
than  their  colleagues,  and  who  were  only  admitted  to  the 
union  in  1882.  A  "holder  up"  may  progress  to  be  a  plater 
or  rivetter  if  he  becomes  competent  for  their  work,  but  only 
on  condition  that  no  member  of  the  superior  grade  is  out  of 
work  in  the  district  in  question.  Similarly,  a  plater,  rivetter, 
or  angle-iron  smith  is  not  allowed  to  change  to  another 
division  of  the  trade  so  long  as  any  member  of  that  division 
is  seeking  employment. 

The  trades  in  which  this  system  of  regulated  progression 
prevails  cannot  be  said  to  be  entirely  "  open,"  as  an  employer 
is  not  permitted  to  promote  a  favourite  operative  in  such  a 
way  as  to  leave  unemployed  any  workman  of  a  higher  grade. 
On  the  other  hand,  regulated  progression  differs  from 
apprenticeship,  in  the  total  absence  of  any  desire  to  reduce 
the  number  of  candidates  below  that  of  places  to  be  filled. 
No  obstacle  is  thus  placed  in  the  way  of  an  expansion  of 
trade  ;  and  when  bad  times  return  there  are  more  operatives 
of  all  classes  than  there  are  places  to  fill.  The  arrangement 
is,  in  fact,  merely  one  for  giving  to  all  the  members  of  each 
grade  the  utmost  possible  continuity  of  employment,  at  the 
cost  of  practically  confining  the  opportunities  of  individual 
promotion  to  the  periods  of  expanding  trade. 

There  are  some  reasons  for  expecting  this  system  of 
regulated  progression  to  become  more  widely  prevalent  in 
British  industry.  It  is  specially  characteristic  of  modern 
trades,  and  the  modern  form  of  business  on  a  large  scale.  It 
is  adapted  to  the  typical  modern  device  of  splitting  up  a 
handicraft  into  a  number  of  separate  processes,  each  of  which 
falls  to  the  lot  of  a  distinct  grade  of  workmen.  It  is  con- 


49 2  Trade  Union  Function 

sistent  with  the  decay  of  apprenticeship,  and  the  "  picking 
up  "  of  each  process  in  turn  by  the  sharp  lad  and  ambitious 
young  mechanic.  It  goes  a  long  way  to  secure  both  the 
main  objects  of  Trade  Unionism,  continuity  of  livelihood, 
and  the  maintenance  of  the  Standard  of  Life.  It  has  no 
invidious  exclusiveness,  or  attempt  at  craft  monopoly.  It 
lends  itself  to  a  combination  of  all  the  different  grades  of 
workmen  in  a  single  industry,  whilst  enabling  each  grade  to 
preserve  its  own  feeling  of  corporate  interest.  What  is  even 
more  significant,  the  system  secures  to  the  manufacturing  opera- 
tives in  large  industries  much  the  same  sort  of  organisation  as 
has  spontaneously  come  into  existence  among  the  great  army 
of  railway  workers,  and  in  the  Civil  Service  itself.  In  the  graded 
service  of  the  railway  world,  whilst  there  is  no  fixed  rule  on 
the  subject,  it  is  usual  for  the  general  manager  and  the 
directors  to  fill  vacancies  in  the  higher  posts  by  selecting  the 
most  suitable  candidates  from  the  next  lower  grade.  New- 
comers enter,  in  the  ordinary  course,  at  the  bottom  of  the 
ladder,  and  progress  upwards  as  vacancies  occur.  In  times 
of  depression,  when  the  staff  remains  stationary,  or  has  to  be 
reduced,  the  contraction  operates  mainly  at  the  bottom. 
Recruiting  for  the  lowest  grade  is  practically  suspended. 
Higher  up,  vacancies  may  remain  unfilled  and  promotion  thus 
be  checked,  but  actual  dismissals  for  want  of  work  are  rare, 
and  are  only  resorted  to  in  cases  of  absolute  necessity.  This 
continuity  of  livelihood,  which  prevails  largely  in  great 
banking  corporations,  and,  indeed,  in  all  extensive  business 
undertakings,  is  still  more  characteristic  of  the  British  Civil 
Service.  The  Postmaster-General,  who  is  by  far  the  largest 
employer  of  labor  in  the  country,  never  dismisses  a  man  for 
lack  of  business,  and  fills  practically  all  the  higher  grades  of 
his  service  by  promotion  from  the  lower  as  vacancies  occur. 
The  union  of  competing  firms  into  great  capitalist  corpora- 
tions or  syndicates,  such  as  those  already  prevailing  in  the 
salt,  alkali,  and  cotton  thread  trades,  and  the  growth  of 
colossal  commercial  undertakings  under  single  management, 
appears  likely  to  bring  with  it,  as  a  mere  matter  of  con- 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  493 

venience  and  discipline,  the  creation  of  a  similarly  graded 
service  in  each  monopolised  industry. 

In  the  case  of  the  Civil  Service,  as  in  the  Army  and 
Navy,  this  system  of  regulated  progression  is  combined 
with  an  objectionable  feature.  Although  here  and  there 
a  man  of  exceptional  ability  or  influence  may  be  pitch- 
forked into  a  high  post,  over  the  heads  of  others,  the  great 
majority  of  vacancies  in  the  upper  grades  are  filled  by 
mere  seniority,  tempered  only  by  the  passing  over  of  officers 
who  are  notoriously  inefficient.  No  such  idea  of  seniority 
is  to  be  found  in  the  Trade  Union  regulations.  The  manager 
of  a  steel  works  has  full  liberty  to  pick  out  the  most  com- 
petent wheel-chargeman  to  be  a  Third  Hand.  He  may  fill 
vacancies  in  the  class  of  Second  Hands  from  the  ablest  of  the 
Third  Hands,  and  then  choose  the  very  best  of  the  Second 
Hands  to  keep  up  the  select  group  of  First  Hands  on  whom 
the  principal  responsibility  rests.1  The  Silk-dressers  leave  it 
absolutely  to  the  employer  to  pick  out,  for  any  vacancy  in 
the  higher  grades,  whichever  workman  in  the  lower  he  may 
think  best  qualified  for  the  place.  Once  a  man  has  been 
deliberately  promoted  by  his  employer  to  a  particular  grade, 
he  is  entitled,  under  the  Trade  Union  system  of  regulated 
progression  as  in  the  Civil  Service,  to  a  preference  for  work 
of  that  or  any  higher  class,  over  any  man  of  an  inferior  grade. 
But  under  these  Trade  Union  regulations  the  members  of 
any  particular  grade  can  urge,  as  among  themselves,  no  other 
claim  than  that  of  superior  efficiency.  The  very  conception 
of  seniority,  as  constituting  a  claim  to  advancement,  is  foreign 
to  Trade  Unionism.  Whatever  arrangements  may  be  made 
to  protect  the  vested  interests  of  those  already  within  the 
circle,  there  is  never  any  idea  of  preferring,  among  the 
candidates  for  admission,  either  those  who  are  oldest  or  those 

1  A  short  period  of  service  in  the  lower  grade  before  promotion  is  sometimes 
stipulated  for  in  the  rules  : — 

"  That  no  person  be  allowed  to  work  (as  a)  second  hand  before  being  one  year, 
nor  (as  a)  first  hand  before  being  three  years  at  the  trade." — Constitution  and 
Rules  of  the  British  Steel  Smelters'  Amalgamated  Association  (Glasgow,  1892), 
p.  30. 


494  Trade  Union  Function 

who  have  served  longest.  It  is  a  special  characteristic 
of  the  industrial  world,  as  compared  with  the  more  genteel 
branches  of  the  public  service,  that  such  special  promotion 
comes,  as  a  rule,  not  to  the  old  but  to  the  young ;  not 
to  the  workman  grown  gray  and  stiff  at  his  mechanical 
task,  but  to  the  clever  young  artisan  who  reveals  latent 
powers  of  initiative  organisation  or  command.1  Against  such 
promotion  according  to  merit  no  Trade  Union  ever  urges  a 
word  of  objection. 

But  although  the  Trade  Union  world  is  singularly  free 
from  any  idea  of  promotion  by  seniority,  there  are,  here  as 
elsewhere,  traces  of  what  may  be  called  local  protectionism, 
in  conflict  with  the  more  general  class  interest.  Thus  it  is 
a  cardinal  tenet  of  the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Opera- 
tive Cotton-spinners  that,  whilst  it  is  for  the  operatives  to 
insist  on  a  universal  enforcement  of  the  Standard  Rate,  it  is 
for  the  employer,  and  the  employer  alone,  to  determine  whom 
he  will  employ.  When  a  pair  of  mules  are  vacant,  the  mill- 
owner  may  entrust  them  to  whomsoever  he  pleases,  provided 
that  the  selected  person  instantly  joins  the  union  and  is  paid 
according  to  the  "  List."  But  the  operatives  in  the  particular 
mill  have  not  infrequently  resented  the  introduction  of  a 
spinner  from  another  mill,  even  if  he  is  a  member  of  their 
own  union,  when  there  are  piecers  who  have  grown  up  in 
the  service  of  the  firm,  and  have  long  been  waiting  for  the 
chance  of  becoming  spinners.  The  able  officials  and  leaders 
of  the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners 
throw  their  weight  against  any  such  feeling  on  the  ground 
that  it  is  inconsistent  with  Trade  Unionism.  The  same  con- 
flict of  the  local  with  the  general  interest  has  come  up  among 
the  Steel  Smelters,  whose  system  of  regulated  progression  is  so 
elaborate.  At  one  branch  (Blochairn  Works,  Glasgow)  the 
Wheel-chargemen  (there  called  "  helpers  ")  objected  to  vacan- 

1  This  is,  to  some  extent,  the  case  also  in  the  more  business-like  branches  of  the 
British  Civil  Service,  where  the  aristocratic  tradition  is  absent.  The  large  graded 
services  of  the  Post  Office,  Customs,  and  Excise  are  mainly  governed  by  a  system 
of  "  promotion  according  to  merit,"  vacancies  being  filled  by  selection  among  the 
next  lower  grade,  irrespective  of  seniority. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  495 

cies  among  the  Third,  Second,  or  First  Hands  in  their  particular 
establishment  being  filled  by  unemployed  men  of  those 
grades,  coming  from  elsewhere.  They  demanded  that  the 
wheel-chargemen,  and  the  men  in  other  lower  grades,  should 
have  a  preference  for  any  vacancies  that  occurred  in  their 
own  steelworks.  Any  such  substitution  of  a  vertical  for  a 
horizontal  cleavage  of  the  trade  would,  it  is  clear,  be  incon- 
sistent with  the  regulated  progression  enforced  by  the  British 
Steel  Smelters'  Amalgamated  Association,  and  would  have 
seriously  hampered  the  employers'  choice  of  operatives. 
The  union  accordingly  refused  to  recognise  the  claim  of  the 
Blochairn  helpers,  and  they  were  eventually  excluded  from 
its  ranks.1 

(d)   The  Exclusion  of  Women 

So  far  we  have  taken  for  granted  that  the  candidate  for 
admission  to  the  trade  belongs  to  the  male  sex.  In  this  we 
have  followed  the  ordinary  Trade  Union  books  of  rules, 
which,  in  nine  cases  out  of  ten,  have  found  no  need  to  refer 
to  the  sex  of  the  members.  The  middle-class  Anglo-Saxon 
is  so  accustomed  to  see  men  and  women  engaged  in  identical 
work  as  teachers,  journalists,  authors,  painters,  sculptors, 
comedians,  singers,  musicians,  doctors,  clerks,  and  what  not, 
that  he  unconsciously  assumes  the  same  state  of  things  to 
exist  in  manual  labor  and  manufacturing  industry.2  But  in 
the  hewing  of  coal  or  the  making  of  engines,  in  the  building 
of  ships  or  the  erecting  of  houses,  in  the  railway  service  or 
the  mercantile  marine,  it  has  never  occurred  to  the  most 

1  We  need  not  do  more  than  mention   the  demand — put   forward  by  the 
Enginemen's  and  the  Plumbers'  Trade  Unions — that  the  possession  of  a  certificate 
of  competency,  awarded  by  some  public  authority,  should  be  made  a  condition  of 
practising  their  respective  trades.      Regulations  of  this  kind  already  govern,  not 
only  the  learned  professions,  but  also  the  mercantile  marine,  and,  to  a  growing 
extent,  the  elementary  school  service.     Protection  of  the  interests  of  the  consumer 
may  possibly  cause  them  to  be  extended  to  some  other  occupations  ;  Massachusetts 
Law  265  of  1896  requires  a  certificate  for  gasfitters. 

2  Similarly,  the  entrance  into  industrial  occupations  of  a  relatively  small  number 
of  middle-class  women  has  given  rise  to  a  quite  disproportionate  impression  as  to 
the  extent  to  which  the  employment  of  women  has  increased ;  see  the  Board  of 
Trade  Report  by  Miss  Collet  on  the  Employment  of  Women  and  Girts,  p.  7, 


496  7^rade  Union  Function 

economical  employer  to  substitute  women  for  men.1  And 
thus  we  find  that,  contrary  to  the  usual  impression,  nine- 
tenths  of  the  Trade  Unionists  have  never  had  occasion  to 
exclude  women  from  their  organisations.  Even  in  the 
industries  which  employ  both  men  and  women,  we  nearly 
always  find  the  sexes  sharply  divided  in  different  depart- 
ments, working  at  different  processes,  and  performing  different 
operations.2  In  the  vast  majority  of  cases  these  several 
departments,  processes,  and  operations  are  mutually  com- 
plementary, and  there  is  no  question  of  sex  rivalry.  In  others 
we  find  what  is  usually  a  temporary  competition,  not  so 
much  between  the  sexes,  as  between  the  process  requiring 
a  skilled  man,  and  that  within  the  capacity  of  a  woman 
or  a  boy  laborer.  Our  chapter  on  "  New  Processes  and 
Machinery  "  has  described  the  Trade  Union  policy  with  regard 
to  the  substitution  of  unskilled  for  skilled  labor.  The 
present  section  has,  therefore,  only  to  treat  of  the  com- 
paratively small  number  of  cases  in  which,  without  any 
change  of  process,  women  attempt  to  learn  the  same  trade 
and  perform  the  same  work  as  men. 

The  intensity  of  the  resentment  and  abhorrence  with 
which  the  average  working  man  regards  the  idea  of  women 
entering  his  trade,  equals  that  displayed  by  the  medical 
practitioner  of  the  last  generation.  We  have,  to  begin  with, 
a  deeply-rooted  conviction  in  the  minds  of  the  most  con- 
servative of  classes,  that,  to  use  the  words  of  a  representative 
compositor,  "  the  proper  place  for  females  is  their  home."8 
The  respectable  artisan  has  an  instinctive  distaste  for  the 
promiscuous  mixing  of  men  and  women  in  daily  intercourse, 

1  The  women  who  worked  in  coalpits  before  the  Mines  Regulation  Act  of 
1842  did  the  work,  not  of  the  coal-hewers,  but  of  boys.     The  sweeping  pro- 
hibition of  women  working  in  underground  mines  happened  not  to  be  a  Trade 
Union  demand,  for  the  miners  were  at  the  moment  unorganised.      It  was  pressed 
for  by  the  philanthropists  on  grounds  of  morality. 

2  See  "The  Alleged  Difference  between  the  wages  of  Men  and  Women,"  by 
Sidney  Webb  (Economic  Journal,  December   1891);    Women  and  the  Factory 
Acts,  by  Mrs.  Sidney  Webb  (Fabian  Tract,  No.  67). 

3  Report  of  Proceedings  of  the  Meeting  of  Delegates  from  the  Typographical 
Societies  of  the  United  Kingdom  and  the  Continent  (London,  1886),  p.  25. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  497 

whether  this  be  in  the  workshop  or  in  a  social  club.1  These 
objections,  which  often  spring  from  mere  old-fashioned 
prejudice,  tend  to  hide,  and  in  the  eyes  of  progressive 
reformers,  to  discredit,  the  Trade  Union  objection  to  a  new 
class  of  "  blacklegs."  No  employer  would  dream  of  sub- 
stituting women  for  men,  unless  this  resulted  in  his  getting 
the  work  done  below  the  men's  Standard  Rate.  The  facts 
that  women  have  a  lower  standard  of  comfort  than  men,  that 
they  seldom  have  to  support  a  family,  and  that  they  are 
often  partially  maintained  from  other  sources,  all  render  them, 
as  a  class,  the  most  dangerous  enemies  of  the  artisan's 
Standard  of  Life.  The  instinctive  Trade  Union  attitude 
towards  women  working  at  a  man's  trade  is  exactly  the 
same  as  that  towards  men  who  habitually  "  work  under 
price,"  except  that  it  is  reinforced  in  the  case  of  women  by 
certain  social  and  moral  prejudices  which,  in  our  day,  and 
among  certain  reformers,  are  beginning  to  be  considered 
obsolete.  But  under  the  pressure  of  the  growing  feeling  in 
favor  of  the  "  equality  of  the  sexes  "  the  Trade  Unions  have, 
as  we  shall  see,  changed  front.  They  began  with  a  simple 
prohibition  of  women  as  women.  From  this  point  we  shall 
trace  the  development  of  a  new  policy,  based,  like  that 
relating  to  new  processes,  not  on  exclusion,  but  on  the 

1  As  regards  many  trades,  there  is  much  force  in  this  objection.  Where 
men  and  women  work  independently  of  each  other,  in  full  publicity,  and  in,  com- 
paratively decent  surroundings,  as  is  the  case  with  the  male  and  female  weavers 
in  a  Lancashire  cotton  mill,  there  is  little  danger  of  sexual  immorality.  But 
where  a  woman  or  girl  works  in  conjunction  with  a  man,  especially  if  she  is 
removed  from  constant  association  with  other  female  workers,  experience  both  in 
the  factory  and  the  mine  shows  that  there  is  a  very  real  danger  to  morality. 
This  is  increased  if  the  work  has  to  be  done  in  unusual  heat  or  exceptional  dress. 
But  the  most  perilous  of  relations  is  that  in  which  the  girl  or  woman  stands  in  a 
position  of  subordination  to  the  man  by  whose  side  she  is  working.  No  one 
acquainted  with  the  relation  between  cotton-spinner  and  piecer  can  doubt  the 
wisdom,  from  the  point  of  view  of  public  morality,  of  the  imperative  refusal  of 
the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners  to  allow  its  members 
to  employ  female  piecers.  Even  in  the  weaving  sheds,  where  the  relations 
between  the  weavers  themselves  are  satisfactory,  the  subordination  of  the  women 
weavers  to  the  male  overlooker  leads  to  frequent  scandals.  The  statutory 
exclusion  of  women  from  working  in  underground  mines  is,  we  believe,  universally 
approved. 

VOL.  II  2  K 


498  Trade  Union  Function 

maintenance  of  a  definite  Standard  Rate  for  each  grade  of 
labor. 

The  eighteenth-century  trade  clubs  of  hatters,  basket- 
makers,  brushmakers,  or  compositors  would  have  instantly 
struck  against  any  attempt  to  put  a  woman  to  do  any  part 
of  their  craft.1  It  is  interesting  that  the  only  case  in  which 
we  can  discover  this  categorical  prohibition  still  actually 
existing  in  a  current  book  of  rules  of  to-day  is  that  of  the 
archaic  society  of  the  Pearl  Button  Makers,  whom  we  have 
already  noticed  as  extreme  in  their  limitation  of  apprentices 
and  unique  in  their  peremptory  prohibition  of  machinery. 
"  No  female  allowed,"  laconically  observes  their  regulation,  "  in 
the  capacity  of  either  piecemaker,  turner,  or  bottomer.  Any 
member  working  where  a  female  does  either  [process]  shall 
forfeit  one  pound,  and  should  he  continue  to  do  so  shall  be 
excluded."2  In  some  other  small  indoor  handicrafts,  where 
the  work  requires  no  great  strength  or  endurance,  employers 
have,  here  and  there,  fitfully  sought  to  teach  women  the  trade. 
The  men,  whether  organised  or  not,  have  done  their  best  to 
exclude  these  new  competitors,  and  the  employers  have  not 
found  the  experiment  sufficiently  successful  to  induce  them 
to  continue  it.3 

Wherever  any  considerable  number  of  employers  have 
resolutely  sought  to  bring  women  into  any  trade  within  their 

1  It  will   be  needless  to  recall  to  the  reader  similar    prohibitions    by  the 
masters'   gilds.      Thus    the    Articles  of  the    London  Girdlers  (1344)  provided 
"that  no  one  of  the  said  trade  shall  set  any  woman  to  work,  other  than  his 
wedded  wife  or  his  daughter."    The  "Braelers"  (brace-makers)  and  Leather-sellers 
of  London  and  the  Fullers  of  Lincoln  had  the  same  rule. — Riley's  Memorials,  pp. 
217,  278,  547  ;  Toulmin  Smith's  English  Gilds,  p.  180. 

2  Rules  and  Regulations  to  be  observed  by  the  Members  of  the  Operative  Pearl 
Button  and  Stud  Worker?  Protection  Society  (Birmingham,  1887),  p.  12. 

3  It  has  sometimes  happened  that  the  women,  though  acquiring  a  certain 
amount  of  skill  in  most  of  the  process,  have  failed  in  some  essential  part.      Thus 
when  an  employer  brought  his  own  daughters  into  the  trade  of  silver-engraving, 
they  were  never  able,  with  all  his  tuition,  to  pick  up  the  knack  of  "pointing" 
their  "gravers."    The  experiment  has  not  been  repeated.     An  attempt  was  made, 
some  years  ago,  to  teach  women  to  be  "  twisters  and  drawers  "  in  a  Lancashire 
cotton   mill.      The  innovation  did  not,  however   spread,   as  the  women  could 
never  do  the  "beaming,"  and  it  has  been  abandoned.      In  this  case,  by  exception, 
the  incident  has  left  its  trace  in  the  Trade  Union  rules.      The  very  exclusive 
society  of  "  Beamers,  Twisters,  and   Drawers"  now  provides  "That  all  malt 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  499 

capacity,  the  Trade  Unions  have  utterly  failed  to  prevent 
them.  The  most  interesting  case  is  that  of  the  compositors.1 
About  1848  the  great  printing  firm  of  M'Corquodale  intro- 
duced women  apprentices  into  its  letterpress-printing  works 
at  Newton-le-Willows  in  Lancashire,  and  this  example  has 
since  been  followed  by  other  employers  in  various  towns. 
There  can  be  no  doubt  that  the  male  compositors,  whether 
Trade  Unionists  or  not,  have  been,  from  first  to  last,  ex- 
tremely hostile  to  this  innovation,  and  that  they  have  done 
their  best  to  prevent  it.  Down  to  1886  all  the  compositors' 
Trade  Unions  expressed,  either  in  their  rules  or  in  their 
practice,  this  uncompromising  policy  of  exclusion.  This 
policy  was  justified  by  the  men  on  the  ground  that  the 
women  worked  far  below  the  Standard  Rate,  and  that 
"  unfair "  employers  made  use  of  them  to  break  down  the 
men's  position.  In  Edinburgh,  for  instance,  the  compositors' 
great  strike  of  1872-73  was  defeated,  and  the  union  reduced 
to  impotence  by  the  importation  of  "  female  blacklegs,"  who, 
as  the  Board  of  Trade  declares,  have  "  completely  revolu- 
tionised the  trade  in  that  city.2  In  London,  where  there  are 
probably  two  hundred  women  compositors,  these  set  up 
"1000  ens"  of  copy  for  5^d.  to  6d.,  as  compared  with  a 
Standard  Rate  which  works  out  at  about  8^d.,  for  work  of 
identical  quantity  and  quality. 

The  compositors'  policy  of  rigid  exclusion  from  member- 
ship failed  to  keep  the  women  out  of  their  trade.  Whenever 
an  employer  thought  it  worth  his  while  to  engage  women 
compositors,  he  ignored  the  union  altogether,  and  set  up  a 
distinct  establishment.  More  than  one  great  London  firm 
has,  for  instance,  a  "  fair  house "  in  the  Metropolis,  where 

persons  wishing  to  learn  the  trade  of  Twisting  and  Drawing,  shall  first  obtain  a 
shop  to  work  at  when  he  has  learned,  and  procure  a  certificate  from  the  manager 
to  show  that  he  has  engaged  him.  No  youth  under  sixteen  years  of  age  shall  be 
allowed  to  learn  the  trade  of  Twisting  and  Drawing,  and  not  then,  unless  there 
be  a  vacancy  in  the  mill  where  he  is  introduced,  and  no  member  out  of  work  on 
the  books." — Rules  of  the  Blackburn  District  of  the  Amalgamated  Beamers, 
Twisters,  and  Drawers'  Association  (Blackburn,  1891),  p.  12. 

1  See    "  Women    Compositors,"    by    Amy    Linnett,    in    Economic  Review, 
January  1892. 

2  Board  of  Trade  Third  Report  on  Trade  Unions,  C.  5808,  1889,  p.  125. 


5OO  Trade  Union  Function 

none  but  Trade  Unionists  are  employed,  and  another  estab- 
lishment in  one  of  the  small  towns  of  the  Home  Counties, 
where  no  Trade  Unionist  works,  and  where  the  employment 
of  women  is  absolutely  unrestricted.  Smaller  firms  employ- 
ing women  take  girl  apprentices,  and  rely  almost  exclusively 
on  female  labor. 

The  futility  of  the  policy  of  exclusion,  combined  with 
the  growth  of  a  Socialistic  disapproval  of  trade  monopoly, 
induced  the  largest  compositors'  society  to  alter  its  tactics. 
In  1886  we  find  the  able  general  secretary  of  the  London 
Society  of  Compositors  (Mr.  C.  J.  Drummond)1  carrying, 
at  an  important  conference  of  all  the  compositors'  Trade 
Unions,  a  resolution  "  that,  while  strongly  of  opinion  that 
women  are  not  physically  capable  of  performing  the  duties 
of  a  compositor,  this  conference  recommends  their  admission 
to  membership  of  the  various  Typographical  Unions  upon 
the  same  conditions  as  journeymen,  provided  always  the 
females  are  paid  strictly  in  accordance  with  scale."2  This 
resolution  has  been  acted  upon  by  the  London  Society  of 
Compositors,  the  most  important  of  the  unions  represented, 
which  is  now  open  to  women  on  exactly  the  same  terms  as 
to  men.3 

What  the  London  Society  of  Compositors  has  only 
lately  discovered,  the  Lancashire  weavers  have,  for  two 
generations,  unconsciously  acted  upon.  Here  there  has 
never  been  any  sex  distinction.  The  various  organisations 
of  weavers  have,  from  the  introduction  of  the  power-loom, 
always  included  women  as  members  on  the  same  terms  as 
men.  The  piecework  list  of  prices,  to  which  all  workers 

1  Now  on  the  staff  of  the  Labor  Department  of  the  Board  of  Trade. 

2  Report  of  Proceedings  of  the  Meeting  of  Delegates  from  the  Typographical 
Societies  of  the  United  Kingdom  and  the  Continent  (London,  1886),  pp.  23-25. 

3  It  is  interesting  to  trace  this  change  of  attitude  among  the  London  com- 
positors, partly  to  a  dim  and  imperfect  appreciation  of  the  foregoing  argument, 
and  partly  also  to  the  growth  of  Socialist  ideas,  and  the  conception  of  equality  of 
rights  ;  see  the  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  pp.  384,  394.     We  believe  that  during 
ten  years  only  one  woman  compositor  has  ever  claimed  admission  to  the  London 
Society  of  Compositors.     On  it  being  proved  that,  employed  at  Mr.  William 
Morris's  Kelmscott  Press,  she  was  paid  at  the  Standard  Rate,  she  was  promptly 
enrolled  as  a  member  (Printing  News ,  October  1892). 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  501 

must  conform,  applies  to  men  and  women  alike.  But  it  is 
interesting  to  observe  that  the  maintenance  of  a  Standard 
Rate  has  resulted  in  a  real,  though  unobtrusive,  segregation. 
There  is  no  attempt  to  discriminate  between  women's  work 
and  men's  work  as  such.  The  uniform  scale  of  piecework 
prices  includes  an  almost  infinite  variety  of  articles  from  the 
plain  calico  woven  on  narrow  looms  to  the  broad  and  heavy 
figured  counterpanes  which  tax  the  strength  of  the  strongest 
man.  In  every  mill  we  see  both  men  and  women  at  work, 
often  at  identical  tasks.  But,  taking  the  cotton-weaving 
trade  as  a  whole,  the  great  majority  of  the  women  will  be 
found  engaged  on  the  comparatively  light  work  paid  for  at 
the  lower  rates.  On  the  other  hand,  a  majority  of  the  men 
will  be  found  practically  monopolising  the  heavy  trade,  priced 
at  higher  rates  per  yard,  and  resulting  in  larger  weekly  earn- 
ings. But  there  is  no  sex  competition.  A  woman  of  excep- 
tional strength,  who  is  capable  of  doing  the  heavy  work, 
cannot  take  advantage  of  her  lower  Standard  of  Life,  to 
offer  her  services  at  a  lower  rate  than  has  been  fixed  for 
the  men.  She  is  not,  as  a  woman,  excluded  from  what  is 
generally  the  men's  work,  but  she  must  win  her  way  by 
capacity,  not  by  underbidding.  On  the  other  hand,  though 
the  rates  fixed  for  the  lighter  work  have  been  forced  up  to 
a  point  that  is  high  relatively  to  the  women's  Standard  of 
Life,  the  wages  that  can  be  earned  at  this  grade  are  too.  low 
to  tempt  any  but  the  weaker  men  to  apply  for  such  looms. 
In  short,  the  enforcement  of  a  definite  Standard  Rate, 
practically  unalterable  in  individual  cases,  serves,  in  itself,  to 
prevent  sex  competition.  The  candidates  for  employment 
tend  to  segregate  into  virtually  non- competing  groups 
according  to  their  grades  of  strength  and  skill.1 

1  This  principle  of  a  classification  of  work,  and  strict  segregation  of  the  sexes, 
is  now  to  be  found  in  various  other  trades.  Thus,  the  very  old-fashioned  society 
of  goldbeaters  sought,  down  to  recent  years,  absolutely  to  exclude  women.  The 
Rules  of  the  Goldbeater?  Trade  Society  (London,  1875)  provided  "That  no  mem- 
ber be  allowed  to  work  for  a  master  who  employs  females  on  the  premises  or 
elsewhere  under  the  penalty  of  immediate  erasure."  But  this  absolute  exclusion 
is  now  given  up  in  favor  of  a  strict  separation  between  the  men's  and  women's 
tasks.  The  later  Rules  of  the  Goldbeaters'  Trade  Society  (London,  1887)  expressly 


502  Trade  Union  Function 

Precisely  the  same  result  has  occurred  in  the  hosiery 
trade,  where  men  and  women  have  for  many  years  belonged 
to  the  same  organisations  and  worked  side  by  side.  Here 
the  machinery  is  undergoing  a  constant  evolution,  one  stage 
of  which  affords  an  interesting  example  of  the  relation  of 
men  and  women  workers.  At  the  beginning  of  1888  the 
men  working  on  "  circular  rib  frames "  found  themselves 
being  ousted  by  the  women  working  at  lower  rates.  They 
accordingly  demanded,  in  March  1888,  that  a  uniform  rate 
of  3d.  per  dozen  should  be  paid  to  men  and  women  alike. 
The  women  protested,  saying  that  if  they  were  to  charge  the 
men's  price  they  would  be  all  dismissed.  A  compromise  was 
agreed  to,  which  allowed  the  women  to  work  at  a  farthing 
per  dozen  less  than  the  men.  This  led  in  May  to  "  the  dis- 
missal of  the  (male)  circular  rib  frame  hands  from  H.'s  firm 
for  women  to  work.  The  farthing  difference  as  agreed  to 
by  the  workpeople  themselves  under  the  pressure  of  circum- 
stances created  the  evil."  ..."  It  seems  to  us,"  continues 
the  Secretary  of  the  Union,  "  that  the  simplest  and  best  way 
of  meeting  the  difficulty  will  be  to  agree  what  frames  shall 
be  a  man's  and  what  a  woman's  job."  From  the  June  report 
we  see  that  this  suggestion  of  the  Executive  Council  was 
adopted  by  both  male  and  female  workers,  it  being  decided 
that  the  women  should  work  the  "  old "  machines  and  the 
men  the  "  new"  ones  !  This  ingenuous  proposal  was  accepted 
by  the  women  until  they  found  that  the  "  old "  machines 
were,  of  necessity,  being  steadily  replaced  by  new  ones. 
Ultimately  an  agreement  was  arrived  at  that  the  men 
should  work  the  large,  or  "  eight -head "  frames,  and  the 
women  the  small,  or  "  six-head  "  frames.  This  segregation 
of  the  sexes  was  secured,  not  by  the  exclusion  of  one 
sex  or  the  other  from  either  machine,  but  an  ingenious 

allow  that  a  member  "  may  work  at  any  shop  where  females  are  employed, 
provided  he  does  not  assist  them  or  be  assisted  by  them  in  any  part  of  the  work." 
And  the  brushmakers,  who  once  strove  against  women  working  at  all,  now  seek 
merely  to  keep  them  to  their  own  class  of  work.  "  Any  member  boring  pan 
or  machine  work  for  women  shall  be  expelled." — General  Trade  Rules  of  the 
United  Society  of  Brushmakers  (London,  1891),  p.  24. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  503 

adjustment  of  the  Standard  Rate.  The  women  retained 
their  privilege  of  working  at  a  farthing  per  dozen  less  than 
the  men,  a  concession  which  gave  them  a  virtual  monopoly 
of  their  own  machine.  On  the  other  hand,  it  was  agreed 
between  the  union  and  the  employers  that,  as  between 
the  "  six-head  "  frame  and  the  "  eight-head  "  frame,  an  extra 
allowance  of  a  farthing  per  dozen  should  be  paid  to  com- 
pensate for  the  lesser  output  of  the  smaller  machine.  This 
prevented  the  smaller  (or  women's)  machine  from  encroaching 
on  the  work  for  which  the  larger  (or  men's)  machine  was 
best  fitted.  The  result  has  been  that,  whilst  their  weekly 
earnings  may  differ  widely,  the  women  actually  obtain  the 
same  rate  per  dozen  on  their  own  machine  as  the  men  do 
on  theirs,  whilst  complete  segregation  of  the  sexes  is  secured, 
and  all  competition  between  men  and  women  as  such  is 
practically  prevented.1 

The  experience  of  the  Lancashire  Cotton-weavers  and  the 
Leicestershire  Hosiers  affords,  we  think,  a  useful  hint  to  the 
London  Society  of  Compositors.  To  complete  its  policy 
with  regard  to  women's  labor,  the  latter  should  not  merely 
admit  to  membership  those  women  who  prove  their  capacity 
to  do  a  man's  work,  but  should  also  take  steps  to  organise 
the  weaker  or  less  efficient  female  compositors  whom  this 
condition  excludes.  As  in  the  case  of  alternative  processes, 
the  welfare  of  each  party  is  bound  up  with  the  maintenance 
of  the  other's  Standard  Rate.  It  is  easy  to  see  that  the 
women  compositors,  as  a  class,  stand  to  lose  if  the  men's 
employers  were  to  regain  the  trade  from  the  firms  employ- 
ing women  by  reducing  the  men's  wages.  On  the  other 
hand,  the  men  suffer  if,  owing  to  the  defenceless  state  of  the 
women  and  their  partial  maintenance  from  other  sources, 
employers  are  able  to  obtain  their  labor  at  wages  positively 
below  what  would  suffice  to  keep  it  in  constant  efficiency,  if 
the  women  depended  permanently  on  their  wages  alone.  To 
prevent  any  such  "  bounty  "  being  indirectly  paid  by  other 

1  Amalgamated  Hosiery  Union,   Monthly  Reports  for    1888  ;  and   personal 
information  in  1893  and  1896. 


504  Trade  Union  Function 

classes  of  the  community  to  the  employer  of  female  labor,  it  is 
necessary  that  the  women  should  be  in  a  position  to  maintain 
a  Standard  Rate  for  their  own  work,  even  though  this  may 
have  to  be  fixed  lower  than  that  of  the  men.  Now,  Trade 
Union  experience  shows  that  the  first  condition  of  the  con- 
temporary maintenance  of  two  different  Standard  Rates,  in 
different  grades  of  the  same  industry,  is  that  there  should  be 
a  clear  and  sharp  distinction  between  them.  In  the  case  of 
the  Cotton-weavers  this  is  secured  by  the  different  kinds  of 
work,  to  each  of  which  a  definite  scale  of  prices  is  assigned. 
The  Hosiery  Workers  accomplish  the  same  result  by  a  differ- 
entiation of  machine.  In  the  case  of  the  Compositors,  though 
there  are  many  kinds  of  work  for  which  women  have  never 
been  found  suitable,  it  is  impossible  to  make  any  complete 
classification  of  men's  work  and  women's  work.  The  only  way 
of  preventing  individual  underbidding  by  persons  of  a  lower 
standard  of  comfort  is  to  segregate  the  women  in  separate 
establishments  or  departments,  and  rigidly  to  exclude  each 
sex  from  those  in  which  the  other  is  employed  in  type- 
setting.1 If  this  segregation,  which  is  desirable  for  moral  as 
well  as  for  economic  reasons,  were  strictly  enforced,  it  would 
be  highly  advantageous  for  the  London  Society  of  Com- 
positors to  recognise  these  women,  and  to  organise  them, 
either  as  a  "  woman's  branch,"  or  as  an  affiliated  society. 
The  women  could  then  collectively  decide  for  themselves  the 
standard  weekly  earnings  that  ought  to  be  demanded  by  the 
ordinary  woman  compositor,  and  get  a  "  scale  "  of  piecework 
prices  for  women's  jobs  worked  out  on  this  basis.  The 
fundamental  necessity  for  the  Compositors,  from  a  Trade 
Union  point  of  view,  is,  therefore,  not  the  exclusion  of 
women  as  women,  but  the  rigid  insistence  that  any 
candidate  for  admission  into  their  particular  branch  of 
the  trade  should  obtain  the  Standard  Rate.  If  women 
are  incapable  of  earning  the  same  piece-work  rate  as  men, 
they  are,  on  this  argument,  rightly  relegated  to  the  easier 

1  This  need  not  exclude  the  employment  of  a  man  in  the  women's  department 
to  do  laboring  or  engineering  work. 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  505 

lines  of  work  in  which  their  lower  standard  of  effort  can 
be  fully  remunerated. 

We  may  now  sum  up  the  present  Trade  Unionist 
position.  The  old  prohibition  of  women  competitors,  against 
which  the  women's  advocates  have  so  often  protested,  was 
as  unnecessary  as  it  was  invidious.  All  that  is  requisite, 
from  a  Trade  Union  point  of  view,  is  that  the  woman's 
claim  for  absolute  equality  should  be  unreservedly  con- 
ceded, and  that  women  should  be  accepted  as  members 
upon  precisely  the  same  terms  as  men.  Nor  can  the  champion 
of  the  "  equality  of  the  sexes "  logically  demand  from  the 
Trade  Unions  any  further  concession.  The  women's  advo- 
cates are,  in  fact,  in  a  dilemma.  If  they  argue  that  women, 
though  entitled  to  equality  of  treatment,  may  nevertheless 
work  "  under  price,"  in  order  to  oust  male  Trade  Unionists 
from  employment,  they  negative  the  whole  theory  and 
practice  of  Trade  Unionism.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  they 
ask  that  women  shall  be  specially  privileged  to  act  as  black- 
legs, without  suffering  the  consequences,  they  abandon  the 
contention  of  an  equality  of  treatment  of  both  sexes. 
Within  the  world  of  manual  labor,  at  any  rate,  "  equality  " 
between  the  sexes  leads  either  to  the  exclusion  of  women 
from  the  men's  trades,  or  else  to  the  branding  of  the  whole 
sex  as  blacklegs. 

There  is,  however,  no  necessity  to  get  into  this  dilemma. 
It  is  unfair,  and  even  cruel,  to  the  vast  army  of  women 
workers,  to  uphold  the  fiction  of  the  equality  of  the  sexes  in 
the  industrial  world.  So  far  as  manual  labor  is  concerned, 
women  constitute  a  distinct  class  of  workers,  having  different 
faculties,  different  needs,  and  different  expectations  from 
those  of  men.  To  keep  both  sexes  in  the  same  state  of 
health  and  efficiency — to  put  upon  each  the  same  degree  of 
strain — implies  often  a  differentiation  of  task,  and  always 
a  differentiation  of  effort  and  subsistence.1  The  Common 

1  Professor  Edgeworth  puts  an  interesting  problem  {Mathematical  Psychics^ 
p.  95).  "When  Fanny  Kemble  visited  her  husband's  slave  plantations,  she 
found  that  the  same  (equal)  tasks  were  imposed  on  the  men  and  the  women,  the 


506  Trade  Union  Fimction 

Rules  with  regard  to  wages,  hours,  and  other  conditions, 
by  which  the  men  maintain  their  own  Standard  of  Life 
are  usually  unsuited  to  the  women.  The  problem  for  the 
Trade  Unionist  is,  whilst  according  to  women  the  utmost 
possible  freedom  to  earn  an  independent  livelihood,  to 
devise  such  arrangements  as  shall  prevent  that  freedom 
being  made  use  of  by  the  employers  to  undermine  the 
Standard  of  Life  of  the  whole  wage -earning  class.  The 
experience  of  the  Lancashire  Cotton -weavers  and  the 
Leicestershire  Hosiers  points,  we  think,  to  a  solution  being 
found  in  the  frank  recognition  of  a  classification  of  work. 
The  essential  point  is  that  there  should  be  no  under-bidding 
of  individuals  of  one  sex  by  individuals  of  the  other.  So 
long  as  the  competition  of  men  is  virtually  confined  to  the 
men's  jobs,  and  the  competition  of  women  to  the  women's  jobs, 
the  fact  that  the  women  sell  their  labor  at  a  low  price  does 
not  endanger  the  men's  Standard  Rate,  and  the  fact  that 
men  are  legally  permitted  to  work  all  night  does  not  diminish 
the  women's  chance  of  employment.  In  the  vast  majority 
of  trades,  as  we  have  seen,  this  industrial  segregation  of  the 
sexes  comes  automatically  into  existence,  and  needs  no  ex- 
press regulation.  In  the  very  small  number  of  cases  in 
which  men  and  women  compete  directly  with  each  other  for 
employment,  on  precisely  the  same  operation,  in  one  and 
the  same  process,  there  can,  we  believe,  be  no  effective  Trade 
Unionism  until  definite  Standard  Rates  are  settled  for  men's 
work  and  women's  work  respectively. 

This  does  not  mean  that  either  men  or  women  need  to 
be  explicitly  excluded  from  any  occupation  in  virtue  of  their 
sex.  All  that  is  required  is  that  the  workers  at  each  opera- 
tion should  establish  and  enforce  definite  Common  Rules, 
binding  on  all  who  work  at  their  operation,  whether  they 
be  men  or  women.  The  occupations  which  demanded  the 

women  accordingly,  in  consequence  of  their  weakness,  suffering  much  more 
fatigue.  Supposing  the  [employer]  to  insist  on  a  certain  quantity  of  work  being 
done,  and  to  leave  the  distribution  of  the  burden  to  the  philanthropist,  what 
would  be  the  most  beneficent  arrangement — that  the  men  should  have  the  same 
fatigue,  or  not  only  more  task,  but  more  fatigue  ?  " 


The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  507 

strength,  skill,  and  endurance  of  a  trained  man  would,  as  at 
present,  be  carried  on  with  a  relatively  high  Standard  Rate. 
On  the  other  hand,  the  operatives  in  those  processes  which 
were  within  the  capacity  of  the  average  woman  would  aim 
at  such  Common  Rules  as  to  wages,  hours,  and  other  con- 
ditions of  labor,  as  corresponded  to  their  position,  efforts,  and 
needs.  The  experience  of  the  Lancashire  Cotton-weavers 
indicates  that  such  a  differentiation  of  earnings  is  not 
necessarily  incompatible  with  the  thorough  maintenance  of  a 
Standard  Rate,  and  also  that  it  results  in  an  almost  com- 
plete industrial  segregation  of  the  sexes.  Women  are  not 
engaged  at  the  men's  jobs,  because  the  employers,  having  to 
pay  them  at  the  same  high  rate  as  the  men,  find  the  men's 
labor  more  profitable.  On  the  other  hand,  the  ordinary 
man  does  not  offer  himself  for  the  woman's  job,  as  it  is  paid 
for  at  a  rate  below  that  which  he  can  earn  elsewhere,  and 
upon  which,  indeed,  he  could  not  permanently  maintain  him- 
self. But  there  need  be  no  rigid  exclusion  of  exceptional 
individuals.  If  a  woman  proves  herself  capable  of  working 
as  well  and  as  profitably  to  the  employer  as  a  man,  and  is 
engaged  at  the  man's  Standard  Rate,  there  is  no  Trade 
Union  objection  to  her  being  admitted  to  membership,  as  in 
the  London  Society  of  Compositors,  on  the  same  terms  as  a 
man.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  a  man  is  so  weak  that  he  can 
do  nothing  but  the  light  work  of  the  women,  these  may. well 
admit  him,  as  do  the  Lancashire  Weavers,  at  what  is  virtu- 
ally the  women's  rate.  The  key  to  this  as  to  so  many  other 
positions  is,  in  fact,  a  thorough  application  of  the  principle 
of  the  Standard  Rate. 


CHAPTER    XI 

THE    RIGHT    TO    A    TRADE 

AN  "  overlap "  between  two  trades,  leading  to  a  dispute  as 
to  which  section  of  workmen  has  a  "  right "  to  the  job,  may 
occur  in  more  than  one  way.  A  new  process  may  be 
invented  which  lies  outside  the  former  work  of  any  one 
trade,  but  is  nearly  akin  to  two  or  more  of  them.  In  such 
a  case,  each  trade  will  vehemently  claim  that  the  new  pro- 
cess "  belongs  "  to  its  own  members,  either  because  the  same 
material  is  manipulated,  the  same  tools  are  used,  or  the  same 
object  is  effected.  But  even  without  a  new  invention  the 
same  conflict  of  rights  may  arise.  The  lines  of  division 
between  allied  trades  have  hitherto  often  differed  from  town 
to  town,  and  the  migration  of  employers  or  workmen,  or 
even  the  mere  imitation  of  the  custom  of  one  town  by  the 
establishments  of  another,  will  lead  to  serious  friction.  A 
new  firm  may  introduce  fresh  ways  of  dividing  its  work,  or 
an  old  establishment  may  undertake  a  new  branch  of  trade. 
There  may  even  be  an  unprovoked  and  naked  aggression, 
by  a  strongly  organised  class  of  workmen,  upon  the  jobs 
hitherto  undertaken  by  a  humbler  section.  In  any  or  all  of 
these  ways,  the  employers  may  find  their  desire  to  allot  their 
work  to  particular  classes  of  workmen  sharply  checked  by 
conflicting  claims  of  "  right  to  the  trade." 

It  is  in  the  great  modern  industry  of  iron-shipbuilding 
that  we  find  the  most  numerous  and  complicated  disputes 
about  "  overlap  "  and  "  demarcation."  The  gradual  trans- 


The  Right  to  a  Trade  509 

formation  of  the  passenger  ship  from  the  simple  Deal  lugger 
into  an  elaborate  floating  hotel  has  obscured  all  the  old  lines 
of  division  between  trades.  Sanitary  work,  for  instance,  has 
always  been  the  special  domain  of  the  plumber,  and  when 
the  sanitary  appliances  of  ships  became  as  elaborate  as  those 
of  houses,  the  plumber  naturally  followed  his  work.  But, 
from  the  very  beginning  of  steam  navigation,  all  iron  piping 
on  board  a  steamship,  whatever  its  purpose,  had  been  fitted 
by  the  engineer.  Hence  the  plumbers  and  fitters  both 
complained  that  "  the  bread  was  being  taken  out  of  their 
mouths  "  by  their  rivals.  We  need  not  recite  the  numberless 
other  points  at  which  the  craftsmen  working  on  a  modern 
warship  or  Atlantic  liner  find  each  new  improvement  bringing 
different  trades  into  sharp  conflict.  The  Engineers  have,  on 
different  occasions,  quarrelled  on  this  score  with  the  Boiler- 
makers, the  Shipwrights,  the  Joiners,  the  Brassworkers, 
the  Plumbers,  and  the  Tinplate  Workers  ;  the  Boiler- 
makers have  had  their  own  differences  with  the  Ship- 
wrights, the  Smiths,  and  the  Chippers  and  Drillers ;  the 
Shipwrights  have  fought  with  the  Caulkers,  the  Boat  and 
Barge  Builders,  the  Mast  and  Blockmakers,  and  the 
Joiners ;  the  Joiners  themselves  have  other  quarrels  with 
the  Mill-sawyers,  the  Patternmakers,  the  Cabinetmakers, 
the  Upholsterers,  and  the  French  Polishers  ;  whilst  minor 
trades,  such  as  the  Hammermen,  the  Ship  Painters,  and  the 
"  Red  Leaders,"  are  at  war  all  round.  Hence  an  employer, 
bound  to  complete  a  job  by  a  given  date,  may  find  one 
morning  his  whole  establishment  in  confusion,  and  the  most 
important  sections  of  his  workmen  "  on  strike,"  not  because 
they  object  to  any  of  the  conditions  of  employment,  but 
because  they  fancy  that  one  trade  has  "  encroached  "  on  the 
work  of  another.  The  supposed  encroachment  may  consist 
of  the  most  trivial  detail.  The  shipwrights  admit  that  the 
joiners  may  case  (or  line  with  wood)  all  telegraph  connections 
throughout  the  ship,  except  only  when  these  happen  to  go 
through  cargo  spaces,  coal  bunkers,  and  the  hold.  When  a 
joiner  passes  this  magic  line  even  in  a  job  of  a  few  hours, 


5io  Trade  Union  Function 

the  whole  of  the  shipwrights  will  drop  their  tools.  On  the 
other  hand,  when  the  joiners'  blood  is  up,  they  will  all  go  on 
strike  rather  than  see  the  shipwrights  do  even  a  few  feet  of 
what  they  regard  as  essentially  their  own  work.  Under  these 
circumstances  a  task  which  one  man  could  do  in  an  hour 
may  stop  a  whole  shipyard.  On  one  occasion,  indeed,  a 
great  shipbuilder  on  the  Tyne,  finding  his  whole  establish- 
ment laid  idle  by  such  a  quarrel,  and  utterly  unable  to  bring 
the  men  to  reason,  finally  took  off  his  coat  and  did  the  disputed 
work  with  his  own  hands.1 

These  trivial  disputes  sometimes  blaze  up  into  industrial 
wars  of  the  first  magnitude.  The  leading  case  which  took 
place  on  the  Tyne  a  few  years  ago  is  thus  described  by  a 
great  shipbuilder.  "For  some  time  before  1890  the  division 
of  work  between  joiners  and  shipwrights  had  led  to  unpleasant 
relations  between  them,  and  to  interference  with  the  progress 
of  work.  .  .  .  The  disputes  became  so  frequent  and  angry 
when  the  large  amount  of  Government  work  came  to  the 
Tyne,  that  the  employers  urged  the  delegates  of  the  two 

1  Demarcation  disputes,  though  frequent  and  serious  in  certain  industries,  are 
entirely  absent  from  some,  and  only  rarely  occur  in  others.  They  are,  for  instance, 
practically  unknown  in  the  textile  trades  and  the  extractive  industries,  which 
together  make  up  a  half  of  the  Trade  Union  world.  It  is  especially  in  the  group 
of  trades  connected  with  the  building  and  equipping  of  ships  that  they  are  trouble- 
some. They  also  occur,  though  to  a  lesser  extent,  throughout  the  engineering 
and  building  trades.  Roughly  speaking,  we  may  say  that  they  are  characteristic 
of  about  one  quarter  of  the  whole  Trade  Union  membership.  We  know  of  no 
systematic  description  or  analysis  of  this  controversy.  The  student  can  only  be 
referred  to  the  materials  relating  to  the  particular  cases  elsewhere  cited,  especially 
the  minutes  of  proceedings  of  the  various  joint  committees,  and  to  the  evidence 
given  before  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor,  45th  day.  (See  Digest  for 
Group  A,  vol.  iii.  C.  6894,  x.  pp.  48-54.)  In  earlier  ages,  when  the  right  to  a 
continuance  of  the  accustomed  livelihood  was  recognised  by  law  and  public  opinion, 
disputes  arising  from  the  encroachments  of  one  craft  on  the  work  of  another  were 
habitually  settled  by  what  was,  in  effect,  a  judicial  decree,  exactly  as  if  the  point 
at  issue  had  been  the  boundary  between  two  landed  estates.  Thus  the  apportion- 
ment of  work  between  the  carpenters  and  the  joiners  was  a  fruitful  cause  of  dispute. 
A  Committee  of  the  Common  Council  of  the  City  of  London  made  an  elaborate 
award  in  1632,  defining  in  detail  the  particular  kinds  of  work  to  be  done  by  the 
Companies  of  Carpenters  and  Joiners  respectively,  "  deal  coffins"  being  assigned, 
as  a  knotty  question,  to  both  in  common.  —  The  History  of  the  Carpenters'  Company^ 
by  Jupp  (London,  1848).  A  similar  dispute  between  the  carpenters  and  joiners 
of  Newcastle-on-Tyne,  who,  down  to  1589,  were  combined  in  a  single  gild,  was 


The  Right  to  a  Trade  5 1 1 

societies  to  refer  their  differences  to  an  independent  and 
capable  arbitrator,  promising  that  they  would,  as  employers, 
accept  any  award  that  he  made.  .  .  .  Mr.  Thomas  Burt,  M.P., 
was  proposed  by  the  joiners  and  accepted  by  the  shipwrights. 
A  very  long,  patient,  and  exhaustive  inquiry  was  made  into 
the  practices  in  the  Tyne  and  other  places,  past  and  present ; 
evidence  was  taken  from  old  hands,  delegates,  and  all  who 
could  throw  light  upon  the  history  of  the  division  of  work.  .  .  . 
After  an  investigation  extending  over  five  and  a  half  months, 
Mr.  Burt  issued  his  award,  allotting,  out  of  168  items  in 
question,  96  to  the  joiners  and  72  to  the  shipwrights. 
The  joiners  .  .  .  disputed  the  fairness  of  the  findings  of  the 
arbitrator  they  had  themselves  proposed,  and  left  their 
employment  for  fourteen  weeks.  .  .  .  Many  vigorous  attempts 
were  made  by  the  employers  to  induce  the  joiners  to  work 
to  the  award  without  success.  .  .  .  Ultimately  .  .  .  the  joiners 
were  called  upon  by  the  united  trades  in  the  Tyne  to  submit 
their  contentions  absolutely  to  a  Committee  or  Court  corn- 
settled  by  an  award  of  similar  character,  "chists  for  corpses  "  being,  curiously 
enough,  equally  made  common  to  the  two  trades  (Beach's  Newcastle  Companies, 
pp.  31-33).  And,  to  turn  to  quite  other  industries,  we  find  the  tanners  and  whit- 
tawyers  disputing  as  to  the  limits  of  their  crafts,  "the  assize  of  a  white  tawyer" 
being,  as  Stow  declared,  "  that  he  make  nor  tawe  no  Ledder  but  Shepe's  Ledder, 
Gotes  Ledder,  Horses'  Ledder,  and  Hindes  Ledder  "  (Jupp,  p.  337),  leaving  to 
the  tanner  the  dressing  of  ox  skins,  which  required  the  use  of  bark.  The  disputes 
between  the  London  Cordwainers  and  the  "  cobelers  from  beyond  sea"  raged  in 
J39S  so  fiercely  that  the  king  "commanded  John  Fresshe,  Mayor  of  the  said  city, 
that  the  said  Cobelers  should  gain  their  living  as  they  had  done  from  of  old  .  .  . 
and  that  it  might  be  declared  what  of  right  should  belong  to  the  one  party  and 
the  other."  Whereupon,  after  solemn  inquiry,  it  was  ordained,  among  other 
things,  "  that  no  person  who  meddles  with  old  shoes  shall  meddle  with  new  shoes 
to  sell."  [Indenture  of  Agreement  between  the  Cordwainers  and  the  Cobblers, 
1 4th  August  1395  ;  Memorials  of  London  and  London  Life,  by  H.  T.  Riley 
(London,  1868),  pp.  539-541.]  This,  however,  did  not  bring  peace,  and  in  1409 
"our  most  dread  lord  the  King  sent  his  gracious  letters  under  his  Privy  Seal 
unto  Drew  Barantyn,"  the  then  Mayor,  which  led  to  renewed  inquiry,  and  a 
more  detailed  apportionment  of  work,  assigning  to  the  cobblers  the  clouting  of 
"  old  boots  and  old  shoes  with  new  leather  upon  the  old  soles,  before  or  behind," 
but  "  that  if  it  shall  happen  that  any  person  desires  to  have  his  old  boots  or 
bootlets  resoled,  or  vamped  and  soled,  or  his  galoches  or  shoes  resoled,  the  same, 
if  it  can  be  done,  shall  pertain  at  all  times  to  the  said  workers  called  Cordwainers 
to  do  it."  [Inquisition  made  for  the  Regulation  of  the  Cordwainers  and  the 
Cobblers,  I5thjune  1409,  Ibid.  pp.  571-574.]  A  detailed  study  of  the  demarca- 
tion disputes  of  former  ages  would  probably  be  of  considerable  interest. 


512  Trade  Union  Function 

posed  of  one  representative  from  six  or  seven  different  trade 
societies.  .  .  .  This  Court,  at  their  first  meeting,  ordered  the 
joiners  to  resume  work  on  Mr.  Burt's  award.  ...  In  January 
1 89 1, the  plumbers  and  fitters  agreed  to  appoint  representatives 
to  discuss  and  settle  the  demarcation  of  their  respective 
trades  .  .  .  owing  to  the  friction  that  was  growing  between 
the  two.  .  .  .  Conferences  between  the  parties  took  place : 
witnesses  were  examined  for  the  fitters  and  for  the  plumbers  ; 
the  practice  for  several  years  back  was  carefully  investigated  ; 
an  agreement  was  eventually  signed  by  the  parties,  but  .  .  . 
it  led  to  disputes  .  .  .  the  moment  it  was  published,  and 
produced  a  strike  as  soon  as  it  was  attempted  to  be  worked 
to.  ...  Each  of  the  two  parties  read  the  provisions  in  utter 
disregard  of  the  other's  views  and  interests,  and  in  equal 
disregard  of  the  interests  of  the  employers,  and  .  .  .  disputed 
points  .  .  .  kept  the  two  trades  apart  for  nine  weeks.  .  .  . 
An  agreement  was  arrived  at,  however,  on  the  i8th  June 
1891,  at  a  conference  between  employers,  fitters,  and 
plumbers.  .  .  .  The  Committee  met  seventeen  times  .  .  . 
settled  two  sections  out  of  a  list  of  twenty-six,  the  Chairman 
giving  his  decision  against  the  objection  of  the  engineers  to 
the  three-inch  limit  on  iron-piping.  .  .  .  The  fitters  rose  in 
a  body,  charged  the  Chairman  with  unfairness,  and  left  the 
Committee  altogether.  .  .  .  The  other  two  parties  .  .  .  issued 
an  award  on  the  28th  October  1891.  The  employers  were 
appealed  to  by  the  plumbers  ...  to  put  the  award  into 
force,  and  did  so,  with  the  result  that  the  fitters  left  their 
employment  .  .  .  and  a  second  strike  ensued  on  the  division 
of  the  same  work  as  before  in  April.  .  .  .  After  a  strike  of 
twelve  weeks  .  .  .  they  [were  driven  to  resume]  work  upon 
the  award  of  the  Joint  Committee.  .  .  .  The  principal 
difficulty  in  composing  the  disputes  has  arisen  from  the 
variety  of  the  practice  in  different  works  and  districts.  .  .  . 
Each  society  proposes  to  itself  to  have  the  largest  possible 
number  of  its  members  employed  at  the  same  time  .  .  .  and 
to  this  end  tries  to  secure  the  whole  of  the  work  it  considers 
belongs  to  its  members  according  to  usage  and  custom.  .  .  . 


The  Right  to  a  Trade  5 1 3 

The   employers'  interest  is   remorselessly  sacrificed    by    the 
disputants."1 

It  will  not,  we  think,  be  difficult  for  the  reader  to  picture, 
even  from  this  bald  narrative,  the  state  of  disorganisation 
and  chaos  into  which  these  recurring  disputes  threw  the 
great  industries  of  Tyneside  between  _  iS^oand  1893. 
Within  the  space  of  thirty-five  months,  there  werePno  tewer 
than  thirry-fivp  weeks  ia-which  one  or  other  of  the  four  most 
important  sections  of  workmen  in  the  staple  industry  of  the 
district  absolutely  refused  to  work.  This  meant  the  stoppage 
of  huge  establishments,  the  compulsory  idleness  of  tens  of 
thousands  of  other  artisans  and  laborers,  the  selling -up  of 
households,  and  the  semi-starvation  of  thousands  of  families 
totally  unconcerned  with  the  dispute.  Nor  was  the  effect 
confined,  as  far  as  the  Trade  Unionists  were  concerned,  to 
these  sensational  but  temporary  results.  The  men  were,  in 
fact,  playing  into  the  hands  of  those  employers  who  wished 
to  see  Trade  Unionism  destroyed.  The  internecine  warfare 
on  the  Tyne  has  left  all  unions  concerned  in  a  state  of  local 
weakness  from  which  they  have  by  no  means  yet  recovered, 
and  under  which  they  will  probably  suffer  for  many  years. 
Their  loss  of  members  and  of  money  is  the  least  part  of 
the  evil.  When  one  society  is  fighting  another,  the  whole 
efficacy  of  Trade  Unionism,  as  a  means  of  improving  the 
conditions  of  employment,  is,  for  the  moment,  paralysed. 
Even  if  the  angry  strife  between  the  two  sets'  of  workmen 
does  not  lead  actually  to  mutual  "  blacklegging,"  it  effectively 

1  Extracted  from  an  interesting  Memorandum  by  Mr.  John  Price,  of  Palmer 
and  Co.,  Limited,  Shipbuilders  and  Engineers,  Jarrow,  which  was  prepared  for 
the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor  but  was  not  published  by  that  body. 

Among  the  voluminous  pamphlet  literature  on  these  disputes  the  most 
important  documents  are  the  several  Reports  of  Conferences  between  the  employers 
and  the  several  engineering  unions  in  Newcastle  on  9th  March,  22nd  March, 
22nd  April,  and  26th  April  1892  ;  the  set  of  Manifestoes  published  by  the  United 
Operative  Plumbers'  Association  (Liverpool,  1892)  ;  the  Report  of  the  Arbitration 
Proceedings  on  the  question  of  the  apportionment  of  work  to  be  done  by  the  Ship- 
wrights and  the  Joiners  (Newcastle,  1890) ;  the  publications  on  the  subject  by  the 
Shipwrights  and  the  Joiners  respectively ;  and  the  Report  of  the  Proceedings  of 
the  Board  of  Conciliation  in  revising  the  award  of  Air.  Thomas  Bitrty  M.P. 
(Newcastle,  1890).  The  Newcastle  Daily  Chronicle  from  1890  to  1893  contains 
frequent  references. 

VOL.  II  2  L. 


5 1 4  Trade  Union  Fimction 

destroys  their  power  of  resisting  any  capitalist  encroachment. 
An  employer  who  desires  to  beat  down  his  men's  terms  need 
only  send,  on  some  trivial  pretext,  for  the  district  delegate  of 
the  overlapping  trade.  The  mere  rumour  that  the  agent  of 
the  rival  union  has  been  seen  to  enter  his  office  will  probably 
excite  sufficient  apprehension  to  bring  his  men  to  instant 
submission.  Thus,  whilst  these  demarcation  disputes  cause, 
to  the  employers,  the  wage-earners,  and  the  community  at 
large,  all  the  moral  irritation  and  pecuniary  loss  of  an 
ordinary  strike  or  lock-out,  they  must,  under  all  circum- 
stances, weaken  all  the  unions  concerned  in  their  struggle 
for  better  conditions. 

We  are,  therefore,  face  to  face  with  an  apparently  in- 
comprehensible problem.  If  the  workmen  have  all  to  lose 
and  nothing  to  gain  by  fighting  over  the  demarcation 
between  trades,  how  is  it  that  their  responsible  leaders  do 
not  peremptorily  interfere  to  prevent  such  quarrels  ?  The 
explanation  is  to  be  found  in  the  character  of  the  workmen's 
claims.  To  them  the  issue  is  not  one  of  expediency,  but  of 
moral  right.  "  We  are  fighting  this  battle,"  declared  the 
United  Pattern-makers'  Association  in  1889,  "on  the  prin- 
ciple that  every  trade  shall  have  the  right  to  earn  its  bread 
without  the  interference  ot  outsiders  ;  a  principle  jealously 
guarded  by  every  skilled  trade  .  .  .  and  one  which  we  are 
fully  determined  shall  likewise  apply  to  us."  *  "  It  is  our  duty," 
declared  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers,  "  to  exercise 
the  same  care  and  watchfulness  over  that  in  which  we  have 
a  vested  interest  as  the  physician  does  who  holds  a  diploma, 
or  the  author  who  is  protected  by  a  copyright." 2  "  The 
machine,"  says  their  Tyne  District  Delegate  in  1897,  "no 
doubt  is  part  of  the  employer's  invested  capital,  but  so  is  the 
journeyman's  skilled  labor."  8  The  Associated  Shipwrights' 
Society  expressly  stated  in  1893,  with  reference  to  a  new 

1  Circular  of  United  Pattern-makers'  Association,  iQth  December  1889. 

2  Preface  to  Rules  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  (London,  1891), 
p.  6. 

3  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers'  Journal,  March  1897. 


The  Right  to  a  Trade  5 1 5 

dispute  on  the  Clyde,  that  "  while  we  do  not  object  to  any 
firms  dividing  their  works  into  departments,  or  sub-letting 
portions  of  the  vessels  they  are  building,  still  we  do  most 
respectfully  and  emphatically  contend  that  no  employers 
should,  in  suiting  their  convenience,  give  away  another  man's 
means  of  living,  any  more  than  that  no  workman  would  be 
allowed  or  justified  to  go  into  an  employer's  office  and  take 
his  money  from  his  safe  and  give  it  to  another." l  "  The 
sacredness  of  property,"  writes  the  Liverpool  Delegate  of  the 
Engineers  in  1897,  "is  surely  applicable  to  labor,  which  is 
as  much  our  property  as  the  lathes  are  the  property  of  the 
employer." 2  And  if  we  look  through  the  reports  of  the 
unions  we  have  mentioned,  or  of  those  in  any  branch  of  the 
building  trades,  we  shall  find  abundant  references,  not  to  the 
pecuniary  advantage  of  the  workmen  or  the  convenience  of 
the  employer,  but  to  "  our  trade  rights,"  or  "  our  universal 
right  and  custom,"  and  to  a  righteous  resistance  of  "  encroach- 
ment, theft,  and  confiscation."  "  Do  the  Bricklayers  aim  at 
extinguishing  us  altogether  ? "  pathetically  remonstrate  the 
Slaters  and  Tilers.  "  They  roam  all  over  a  building  from  the 
cellar  to  the  highest  point,  devouring  everything  and  any- 
thing that  they  choose,  no  matter  what  other  trade  it  may 
belong  to — slating,  roof-tiling,  wall-tiling,  floor-tiling,  paving, 
setting  stone  landings,  sills,  heads,  and  steps,  plastering, 
knobbing,  whitewashing,  etc."  3 

It  is,  fortunately,  unnecessary  for  us  to  discuss  the  work- 
man's initial  assumption  that  it  is  desirable,  in  the  public 

1  Minutes  of  Line  of  Demarcation  Joint-  Committee  of  Shipwrights  and  Joiners 
(Glasgow,  1893),  Part  II.  P-  7>  "The  Shipwrights'  Statement." 

2  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers' Journal,  March  1897. 

3  Correspondence  in  the  Star,  quoted   in   Builder,  8th  April   1893.      This 
sense  of  wrong  is  aggravated  by  an  exaggerated  consciousness  of  the  pecuniary 
drain  on  the  union  funds  involved  in  the  payment  of  out-of-work  benefit  to  the 
displaced    members.       At  a   branch   meeting  attended  by  one  of  the  authors, 
when  a  demarcation  dispute  was  under  discussion,  the  fact  that  the  work  wrong- 
fully engrossed  by  the  rival  trade  would  have  sufficed  to  take  three  unemployed 
members  off  the   books,   and   so  save   this  great  amalgamated  union  thirty-six 
shillings  a  week,  was  repeatedly  adduced  as  a  reason  for  aggressive  action.     The 
aggressive  action  subsequently  cost  that  same  union,  at  the  lowest  computation, 
many  thousands  of  pounds. 


516  Trade  Union  Function 

interest,  for  him  to  be  assured  of  a  reasonable  continuity  of 
livelihood.1  Nor  need  we  here  determine  whether,  if  it 
were  possible  to  secure  this  end  by  fencing  off  each  craft 
from  encroachment,  the  social  advantage  of  this  assurance  of 
livelihood  would  or  would  not  outweigh  the  drawbacks  of  the 
expedient.  It  so  happens  that  in  the  advanced  industrial 
communities  of  our  time,  the  circumstances  are  so  complex, 
and  so  perpetually  changing,  that  it  passes  the  wit  of  man 
to  define  the  "right  to  a  trade"  in  any  way  that  will  not 
produce  the  most  palpable  absurdities. 

The  first  attempt  is  always  to  base  the  right  on  custom. 
It  is  natural  enough  that  the  workmen  in  any  one  town  should 
expect  and  desire  that  the  prevailing  habits  of  work  should 
be  adhered  to.  But  irrespective  of  the  fact  that  the  "  custom 
of  the  trade  "  is  found  to  vary  from  town  to  town,  and  even 
from  establishment  to  establishment,  it  is  obvious  that  this 
affords,  of  itself,  no  rule  when,  as  is  almost  invariably  the 
case,  the  point  at  issue  is  some  novel  process  or  some  hitherto 
unfamiliar  product.  Each  party  then  interprets  the  custom 
in  a  different  way.  It  may  at  first  sight  seem  to  be  con- 
venient to  take,  as  a  guide,  the  object  or  purpose  of  the 
product.  The  shipwrights,  in  fact,  will  sometimes  claim  as 
their  right  all  that  concerns  the  construction  and  fitting  of 
ships.  But  a  modern  ship  now  includes  everything  that  is 
found  in  a  luxurious  hotel ;  and  a  shipwright,  on  this  inter- 
pretation, would  not  only  have  to  work  in  steel  as  well  as  in 
wood,  but  would  also  have  to  be  an  accomplished  engineer, 
boilermaker,  brassfinisher,  plumber,  joiner,  cabinetmaker, 
French  polisher,  upholsterer,  painter,  decorator,  and  electric 
light  and  bell  fitter.  And  if,  in  search  of  some  dividing  line 
between  these  manifestly  different  crafts,  we  turn  to  the  tools 
required,  we  come  to  no  less  incongruous  results.  Fifty 
years  ago  it  would  have  been  admitted  without  question  that 
it  was  for  the  shipwright  to  use  the  adze  and  the  mallet,  and 
for  the  joiner  to  employ  the  hammer  and  the  plane.  But 
the  deck  of  a  modern  passenger  steamer  cannot  be  completed 

1  We  recur  to  this  point  in  our  chapter  on  "  Trade  Union  Assumptions." 


The  Right  to  a  Trade  5 1 7 

without  using  all  these  tools,  together  with  others  borrowed 
from  the  cabinetmaker  and  glazier,  and  machines  altogether 
unheard  of  in  former  times.  If  each  craft  is  to  be  confined 
to  the  tools  which  have  characterised  it  from  time  immemorial, 
the  ship  would  be  crowded  with  workmen  each  waiting  for 
the  moment  to  perform  his  little  bit  of  the  common  task  ; 
all  responsibility  for  the  watertight  character  of  the  deck 
would  be  lost,  and  there  would  still  be  altercations  as  to  who 
should  use  the  newly -invented  machines.  Nor  does  the 
material  used  afford  us  any  dividing  line.  If  this  were 
accepted,  the  advance  of  sanitation,  with  the  disuse  of  leaden 
pipes,  would  involve  the  ousting  of  the  whole  body  of 
certificated  plumbers,  in  favor  of  engineers  and  bricklayers 
destitute  of  sanitary  knowledge.  Moreover,  in  the  crucial 
instances  of  demarcation  trouble,  the  material  concerned  is 
common  to  both  parties.  Shipwrights,  joiners,  and  cabinet- 
makers all  work  in  wood  ;  and  shipwrights,  boilermakers, 
engineers,  tinplate  workers,  and  plumbers  all  handle  iron. 
If  the  substance  fails  to  afford  a  dividing  line,  the  disputants 
will  often  fall  back  on  its  thickness.  The  central  point  in 
dispute  on  the  Tyne  for  two  years  may,  in  fact,  be  said  to 
have  resolved  itself  into  whether  the  limit  of  size  of  the  iron 
pipes  to  be  fitted  by  the  engineers  and  the  plumbers 
respectively,  should  be  2\  or  3  inches,  and  whether  the 
joiners  should  or  should  not  be  confined  to  wood-work  of 
\\  inch  thickness.1  The  demarcation  disputes  between  the 
boilermakers  on  the  one  hand,  and  the  Chippers  and  Drillers 

1  "Mr.  Ramsey  (Shipwrights). — The  question  of  the  thickness  of  material  is 
again  introduced.  I  ask  is  it  fair  that  the  joiner  trade  should  have  all  the  say 
as  to  thickness  of  wood  ?  Is  it  not  a  fact  that  both  trades  manipulate  all  thicknesses 
of  wood  in  their  jobs  ?  We  lay  and  fix  any  kind  of  feathered  and  grooved  ceiling 
in  cargo  spaces  in  the  hold  of  a  vessel.  .  .  .  We  have  objected  all  along  to  this 
Joint  Committee  dealing  with  this  question  of  thickness  of  wood  because  we  con- 
sider the  principle  is  not  sound.  .  . 

"  Mr,  Roger  (Joiners). —  .  .  .  Have  we  not  the  same  liberty  as  a  trade  to 
introduce  a  thickness  as  the  other  side  has  to  object  to  it  ?  .  .  .  We  hold  we  are 
not  exorbitant  in  our  claim  for  lining  i^  inches  and  under.  It  stands  to  reason 
that  joiners  are  the  more  competent  men  to  do  that  class  of  work.  I  would  like 
to  ask  the  other  side  where,  in  the  ancient  shipbuilding  from  Noah  up  to  fifty 
years  since,  they  used  nails  for  fastening.  .  .  .  We  claim  all  lining  from  i£  inches 


518  Trade  Union  Function 

on  the  other,  turn  chiefly  on  the  size  of  the  holes  which  each 
trade  may  cut  in  the  iron  plates.1  The  doctrine  of  the  right 
to  the  trade  thus  leads  us  to  the  absurd  result  that  a  par- 
ticular task  has  to  be  allotted  to  one  trade  or  another,  not 
according  to  its  acquaintance  with  the  purpose  to  be  served, 
or  to  its  familiarity  with  the  tools  or  material  used,  but  ac- 
cording to  the  exact  thickness  of  the  pipe  or  board,  or  the 
precise  diameter  of  the  hole  in  the  iron  plates,  which  the 
fad,  fashion,  or  science  of  the  hour  may  prescribe.  -The 
necessity  of  discovering  some  line  which  can  be  precisely 
defined  and  accurately  measured,  leads,  in  fact,  to  a  purely 
arbitrary  distribution  of  work,  which  has  the  added  demerit 
of  the  greatest  possible  instability. 

all  this  turmoil  the  employers  have  an  easy 
remedy.  "  The  proper  cure,"  declared  the  representative  of 
the  Belfast  shipbuilders,  "  is  to  revert  to  the  old  state  of 
affairs,  where  the  employer  selected  the  men  most  suited  to 
do  the  work  "  ;  or,  as  the  representative  of  the  Tyneside  ship- 
builders put  it,  "  to  uphold  the  right  of  an  employer  to  employ 
whatever  workmen  he  believes  will  best  serve  the  purposes 
of  his  trade  or  business  without  any  regard  to  trade 
societies."  And  the  Scottish  shipbuilders  declared  through 
their  representative,  that  "  whether  a  plumber  may  join 
a  2 -inch  pipe,  but  not  one  of  2^  inches,  whether  a 
joiner  may  dub  a  plank  or  a  shipwright  may  plane  a  rail, 
must  appear  to  a  disinterested  person  extremely  trivial  ; " 
and  they  proposed  summarily  to  "  get  rid  altogether  of  this 
fertile  cause  of  quarrel  by  abolishing  all  arbitrary  boundaries 

and  under,  simply  because  it  is  material  we  are  in  the  habit  of  working,  and 
because  it  is  fastened  to  the  grounds.  .  .  . 

"  Mr.  Wilkie  (Shipwrights). —  ...  In  past  years  when  there  was  no  ma- 
chinery [the  joiners]  might  have  made  this  claim,  but  that  has  all  disappeared  with 
the  introduction  of  machinery.  .  .  .  The  joiners  lay  claim  to  this  work  because  the 
vessels  carry  passengers  one  way.  I  hold  our  claim  is  far  more  legitimate,  seeing 
they  carry  cargo  the  other  way.  .  .  .  Clearly,  if  it  is  to  be  fitted  up  for  cargo  it 
is  shipwrights'  work  pure  and  simple." — Minutes  of  Line  of  Demarcation  Joint- 
Committee  of  Shipwrights  and  Joiners  (Glasgow,  1893). 

1  Report  of  Proceedings  of  the  Sixth  Annual  Meeting  of  the  Federation  of 
Engineering  and  Shipbuilding  Trades  (Manchester,  1896). 


The  Right  to  a  Trade  5 1 9 

between  different  handicrafts,  and  leaving  it  to  the  master 
...  to  settle  .  .  .  how  work  is  to  be  distributed.  .  .  ." 

To  the  reader  of  the  foregoing  chapters,  the  Trade 
Union  objection  to  any  such  abolition  of  the  boundaries 
between  craft  and  craft  will  at  once  be  clear.  If  there  is  to 
be  concerted  action  among  the  workmen — if,  for  instance, 
there  is  to  be  any  representative  machinery  for  Collective 
Bargaining, — it  is  absolutely  necessary  that  the  membership 
of  each  Trade  Union  should  be  precisely  defined,  so  that 
each  workman  may  know  by  what  collective  agreements  he 
is  bound.1  It  is,  in  fact,  a  condition  of  any  organisation  by 
trades  that  the  lines  between  the  trades,  though  not  necessarily 
unalterable,  should  not  be  wantonly  infringed  at  the  mere 
caprice  of  a  single  employer. 

But  there  is  a  further  objection.  If  an  individual  em- 
ployer were  free,  without  encountering  any  resistance  from 
the  Trade  Union  concerned,  to  dispense  with  the  services  of 
men  to  whom  he  was  paying  the  agreed  Standard  Rate,  and 
to  hand  their  work  over  bit  by  bit  to  some  other  sections  of 
workmen,  whom  he  could  induce — perhaps  actually  through 
their  own  Trade  Union — to  work  at  a  lower  price,  all  hope 
of  maintaining  a  Standard  Rate  for  the  more  highly  skilled 
unions  would  be  at  an  end.  Unless  a  Trade  Union  is  to 
give  up  its  whole  case,  it  is  bound,  at  all  hazards,  to  maintain 
the  principle  that  the  Standard  Rate,  agreed  to  by  the 
associated  employers,  shall  be  paid,  in  all  establishments,  for 
all  the  kinds  of  work  to  which  it  was  mutually  intended  to 
apply. 

A  solution  has  therefore  to  be  found  which,  whilst  pro- 
tecting the  employer  against  the  intolerable  annoyance  of 
unprovoked  stoppages,  the  worry  caused  by  any  friction 
between  trades,  and  the  loss  occasioned  by  "  overlap "  of 
work,2  shall  guarantee  the  Trade  Unionists  against  encroach- 

1  This  would  obviously  be  even  more  necessary  than  at  present  if  the  Duke  of 
Devonshire's  proposal  to  make  these  collective  agreements  legally  enforcible  were 
adopted  ;  see  the  chapter  on  "The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining." 

2  "A  further  and  most  material  point  in  the  estimation  of  the  employer,  and 
largely  affecting  his  interest  in  cheapening  and  expediting  the  work,  lies  in  the 


520  Trade  Union  Function 

ments  on  their  Standard  Rate,  and  prevent  any  undermining 
of  their  organisation.  The  experience  of  the  last  few  years 
points,  we  think,  to  the  need,  if  they  are  to  cope  with  the 
difficulty,  for  the  development  of  new  structure  in  the  Trade 
Union  world,  and  for  the  adoption  of  a  new  principle. 

When  a  demarcation  dispute  now  occurs  between  two 
well-organised  trades,  the  first  attempt  of  their  more  reason- 
able representatives  is  to  come  to  a  mutual  agreement  as  to 
how  the  work  should  be  divided  between  them.  Thus  the 
numerous  differences  between  the  Boilermakers  and  the 
Engineers  at  Cardiff  were  amicably  settled  in  1891  by  a 
formal  treaty  between  the  local  branches.1  But  such 
negotiations  will,  like  other  Collective  Bargaining,  occasionally 
end  in  a  deadlock.  Here  we  have  a  case  for  which  arbitration 
would  seem  to  be  specially  fitted.  There  is,  it  is  true,  no 
dominant  assumption  shared  by  both  sides  on  which  the 
award  can  be  based.  But  all  the  trades  concerned  accept, 
in  principle,  the  same  inconsistent  array  of  different 
assumptions,  and  the  decision  cannot,  as  we  have  seen,  be 
other  than  an  arbitrary  one.  The  main  requirement,  there- 
fore, is  that  the  arbitrator  should  not  be  suspected  of  being 
influenced  by  any  other  assumption  than  those  admitted  by 

necessity  there  is  that  no  one  trade  should,  what  is  called,  '  overlap '  another. 
Which  means  that  when  one  trade  takes  up  a  job  on  which  others  are  to  be  sub- 
sequently engaged  before  it  is  completed,  the  work  shall  be  so  divided  to  each, 
that  each  in  due  rotation  shall  complete  his  share  before  the  next  commences  upon 
his  share,  and  that  when  the  last  has  finished  his  portion  the  job  shall  be  finished 
too.  This  is  necessary  to  secure  economy,  quickness,  and  to  fix  responsibility  in 
the  performance  of  the  job." 

1  This  treaty  is  embodied  in  the  "  Ports  of  Cardiff,  Penarth,  and  Barry  By- 
laws "  signed  by  five  representatives  of  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  five 
of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers,  one  of  the  Steam-Engine  Makers' 
Society,  and  one  of  another  smaller  body  of  engineers.  The  preamble  is  as  follows : 
"  For  the  purpose  of  more  clearly  defining  and  setting  forth  particular  questions  in 
dispute,  and  in  consequence  of  certain  misunderstandings  arising  between  members 
of  the  Boilermakers'  Society  and  those  of  the  above-named  engineers,  respecting 
their  respective  claims  to  particular  jobs  in  connection  with  the  art  of  boilermaking 
and  iron  shipbuilding,  we  hereby  agree  that  the  undermentioned  jobs  may  be 
worked  at  in  the  above  ports  by  the  respective  parties  without  let  or  hindrance." 
The  by-laws  consist  of  five  printed  pages  of  technical  details,  providing  for  the 
assignment  of  certain  specified  work  to  the  boilermakers  and  the  engineers 
respectively. 


The  Right  to  a  Trade  5  2 1 

the  parties.     This  points  to  the  establishment  of  a  tribunal 
by  the  Trade  Unions  themselves. 

We  see  such  a  tribunal  arising  in  the  Federation  of  the 
Engineering  and  Shipbuilding  Trades,  to  which  we  have  more 
than  once  alluded.  During  the  last  seven  years  innumerable 
cases  of  "  overlap  "  and  "  encroachment  "  have  been  quietly 
disposed  of  by  this  tribunal,  to  the  general  satisfaction  of 
all  concerned.  The  transformation  of  the  Executive  Council 
of  this  Federation,  formed  of  the  chief  salaried  officials  of 
fourteen  unions,  into  a  supreme  court  of  arbitration  in 
demarcation  disputes  takes  place  in  the  simplest  manner.1 
If  the  Boilermakers  of  any  port  make  a  complaint  that  the 
Smiths  are  encroaching  on  their  trade,  neither  party  is 
allowed  to  cause  any  stoppage  of  work,  and  the  Federal 
Executive  is  summoned  to  meet  at  a  convenient  centre. 
The  officials  of  the  two  trades  concerned  bring  up  their 
witnesses  and  act  as  advocates.  If  the  council  is  not  satisfied 
that  all  the  facts  have  been  brought  out,  two  members — 
say  the  general  secretaries  of  the  Steam  Engine  Makers' 
and  Shipwrights'  societies — are  deputed  to  investigate  the 
dispute  on  the  spot,  to  consult  with  the  employer,  and  to 

1  The  present  rule  is  as  follows : — 

Dispute  between  Societies. — If  any  dispute  takes  place  between  any  of 
the  societies  forming  this  Federation,  unless  amicably  settled,  such  dispute  shall 
be  referred  to  a  Court  of  Arbitration  selected  by  the  parties  affected  by  the 
dispute.  When  a  Court  is  required  the  parties  shall,  if  possible,  mutually  agree 
upon  three  disinterested  referees  ;  failing  this,  each  party  to  the  dispute  shall 
appoint  one  or  two  Arbitrators,  who  must  be  Trade  Unionists  ;  the  two  or  four 
Arbitrators  to  appoint  an  Umpire,  and,  in  the  event  of  the  Arbitrators  failing  to 
agree,  his  decision  shall  be  final  and  binding.  The  Umpire  shall  not  be  selected 
from  any  trade  which  may  come  into  conflict  with  either  of  the  parties  to  the 
difference.  If  a  Court  of  Arbitration  is  not  appointed  within  one  month  of  an 
application  being  made  for  a  reference  to  arbitration,  the  Executive  shall  have 
power  to  step  in  and  appoint  either  Arbitrators  or  Umpire,  as  the  case  might  be. 
The  Court,  when  formed,  to  decide  as  to  place  of  meeting,  method  of  procedure, 
etc.  ;  each  party  to  pay  half  of  the  expenses,  unless  otherwise  ordered  by  the 
Court.  That  when  a  Court  of  Arbitration  is  required  by  any  society  in  the 
Federation  the  Executive  of  said  society  shall  notify  the  Secretary  of  the 
Federation,  who  shall  then  write  to  the  other  party  affected  to  appoint  an 
Arbitrator  or  Arbitrators  as  the  Federation  rules  prescribe. — Report  of  Proceed- 
ings of  the  Fifth  Annual  Meeting  of  Federation  of  Engineering  and  Shipbuilding 
Trades  (Manchester,  1895). 


522  Trade  Union  Function 

report  to  a  future  meeting,  when  a  decision  is  come  to.  The 
ten  or  twelve  experienced  Trade  Union  officials,  who  thus 
adjust  the  differences  between  trade  and  trade,  form  an 
almost  ideal  body  for  this  purpose.  They  are  free  not  only 
from  personal  but  also  from  class  bias.  Whether  2\  inch 
iron  piping  shall  be  fixed  by  an  engineer  or  a  plumber  is 
of  no  consequence  to  the  pattern-maker  or  the  shipwright. 
Whether  cabin  lockers  are  to  be  prepared  by  the  cabinet- 
maker and  fixed  by  the  joiner,  or  whether  either  trade  should 
begin  and  finish  the  whole  job,  is  a  matter  of  indifference  to 
the  plater  or  the  ironmoulder.  Neither  directly  nor  indirectly 
have  the  adjudicators  any  other  interest  than  that  of  prevent- 
ing all  stoppage  of  work  by  effecting  a  permanent  settlement. 
In  this  task  they  are  aided  by  the  fact  that  they  start  with 
the  same  stock  of  unconscious  assumptions  as  both  the 
trades  concerned.  Such  arguments  as  "  priority,  position, 
and  purpose,"  which  appear  to  the  aggrieved  capitalist  as 
fantastic  and  irrelevant  as  the  lawyer's  doctrine  of  "  common 
employment"  does  to  the  injured  workman,  receive  that 
serious  attention  which  their  iteration  on  both  sides  demands. 
The  adjudicators  are  steeped  in  the  technical  details  of  the 
workshop,  from  processes  and  material  to  the  evasions  of  the 
employers  and  the  tricks  of  the  workmen.  They  possess,  in 
fact,  to  the  full,  the  highest  possible  qualification  of  a  judicial 
authority,  the  unbounded  confidence  of  the  disputants,  not 
only  in  their  knowledge  and  sympathy,  but  also  in  their 
absolute  impartiality  as  regards  the  issues  in  dispute. 
Finally,  it  is  no  small  advantage  that,  although  their  award 
has  no  legal  validity,  it  carries  with  it  a  certain  latent  coercive 
authority.  It  would  be  difficult,  if  not  impossible,  for  any 
constituent  body  of  the  Federation  deliberately  to  disregard 
an  award  to  which  it  had  consented,  without  incurring  the 
serious  penalty  of  finding  its  members  practically  excluded 
from  employment  by  a  general  boycott  of  the  other  workmen.1 

1  We  may  here  remind  the  reader  how,  in  our  chapter  on  "  Interunion  Rela- 
tions," we  pointed  out  that  a  federation  of  heterogeneous  bodies  would  not  be  stable 
if  based  on  simple  majority  rule.  It  is  interesting  to  notice  that  the  success  of 


The  Right  to  a  Trade  523 

But  though  a  tribunal  of  this  kind  may,  in  demarcation 
cases,  cut  the  Gordian  knot,  neither  its  deliberations  nor 
its  awards  can  permanently  command  confidence  unless  it  is 
able  to  map  out  some  definite  and  consistent  policy,  accepted 
by  its  litigants  and  adhered  to  in  all  its  own  decisions. 
Moreover,  it  cannot  permanently  secure  industrial  peace 
unless  this  policy  coincides  with  the  interests  of  the  em- 
ployers and  is  based  on  some  assumption  in  which  they  can 
agree.  Such  a  policy  cannot  be  found  in  any  doctrine  of 
"  the  right  to  a  trade,"  because,  as  we  have  shown  in  the 
crucial  instances  of  new  kinds  of  work,  both  parties  may, 
with  equal  reasonableness,  claim  that  equity  is  on  their 
side.  The  solution  of  the  problem  is  to  be  found  in  quite 
another  direction.  It  is  admitted  that,  within  the  limits  of 
a  single  trade  and  a  single  union,  it  is  for  the  employer,  and 
the  employer  alone,  to  decide  which  individual  workman  he 
will  engag;e,  and  upon  which  particular  jobs  he  will  employ 
him.  What  each  Trade  Union  asks  is  that  the  recognised 
Standard  Rate  for  the  particular  work  in  question  shall  be 
maintained  and  defended  against  possible  encroachment. 
If  the  same  conception  were  extended  to  the  whole  group  of 
allied  trades,  any  employer  might  be  left  free,  within  the 
wide  circle  of  the  federated  unions,  to  employ  whichever  man 
he  pleased  on  the  disputed  process,  so  long  as  he  paid  him 

the  Federation  of  the  Engineering  and  Shipbuilding  Trades  as  a  court  of  arbitra- 
tion is  entirely  dependent  on  its  frank  abandonment  of  any  idea  of  representation 
in  proportion  to  membership.  Every  union  admitted,  whether  large  or  small, 
sends  two  representatives  to  the  annual  meeting,  which  elects  one  from  each 
trade — invariably  its  salaried  official — to  form  the  federal  executive.  It  is 
obvious  that  if  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers  or  the  Amalgamated  Society 
of  Carpenters  insisted  on  having  twenty  times  the  amount  of  representation  or 
voting  power  as  the  Associated  Blacksmiths  or  the  United  Pattern-makers,  these 
latter  would  have  no  confidence  in  any  award  of  an  executive  on  which  their 
rivals  had  so  predominant  a  voice.  Unfortunately,  this  very  idea  of  equality, 
which  has  been  a  condition  of  the  success  of  this  federation,  has  hitherto  stood  in 
the  way  of  the  adhesion  of  the  largest  society  concerned  in  the  engineering 
and  shipbuilding  trades.  The  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers,  claiming  to 
include  within  its  own  ranks  all  sections  of  skilled  engineering  mechanics,  has 
hitherto  found  it  inconsistent  with  its  dignity  to  associate  on  equal  terms  with  such 
smaller  sectional  societies  as  the  United  Pattern-makers'  Association  and  the 
Associated  Blacksmiths.  Here  again  the  idea  of  an  all-embracing  amalgamation 
has  prevented  the  effective  organisation  of  the  Trade  Union  world. 


524  Trade  Union  Function 

the  Standard  Rate  agreed  upon  for  the  particular  task.  The 
federated  Trade  Unions,  instead  of  vainly  trying  to  settle  to 
which  trade  a  task  rightfully  belongs,  should,  in  fact,  confine 
themselves  to  determining,  in  consultation  with  the  associated 
employers,  at  what  rate  it  should  be  paid  for} 

If  this  simple  principle  were  adopted, — say,  in  the  great 
shipbuilding  yards  of  the  North-East  coast, — and  if  it  were 
frankly  accepted  by  the  associated  employers  and  the 
Federation  of  Engineering  and  Shipbuilding  Trades,  the 
way  would  clear.  The  Standard  Rate  within  the  un- 
questioned domain  of  each  particular  trade  would  be  deter- 
mined, as  at  present,  by  Collective  Bargaining  between  the 
associated  employers  and  the  Trade  Union  concerned.  But 
directly  any  dispute  arose  as  to  which  trade  a  job  should 
belong — whether  between  employer  and  workman,  or  between 
different  sections  of  wage-earners — the  Collective  Bargaining 
as  to  the  rate  of  payment  for  that  job  would  at  once  pass 
out  of  the  hands  of  both  the  unions  concerned,  and  would 
be  undertaken,  on  behalf  of  the  whole  body  of  allied  trades, 
by  the  Federation.  The  dispute  would,  therefore,  be  referred 
to  the  federal  officials  to  negotiate,  with  the  representatives 
of  the  associated  employers,  a  definite  Standard  Rate  for  that 
particular  task.  In  determining  this  special  rate,  they  would 
be  guided  solely  by  the  character  of  the  work  relatively  to 
other  operations  in  the  same  district.  When,  as  in  the 
notorious  disputes  between  the  fitters  and  plumbers,  and  the 
joiners  and  shipwrights,  the  earnings  of  both  sets  of  work- 
men were  practically  identical,  and  the  volume  of  work  in 

1  This  suggested  solution  has  now  been  tentatively  put  forward  by  the  young 
man  of  exceptional  ability  who  in  1896  became  general  secretary  of  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers.  Writing  on  the  dispute  with  the  Federation 
of  Engineering  Employers  as  to  the  employment  of  laborers  on  machines,  Mr. 
George  Barnes  declared  that  "  the  whole  question  from  our  point  of  view  is 
really  one  of  wages,  and  inasmuch  as  the  employers  disclaim  any  intention  of 
invading  our  territory  as  skilled  mechanics,  we  believe  that  a  mutually  satisfactory 
solution  of  the  difficulty  is  to  be  found  in  local  joint  committees,  with  a  reference 
to  the  Board  of  Trade  :  such  committees  to  decide — having  due  regard  to  class  of 
machines,  quality  of  work,  and  standard  rate  of  district — upon  the  -wage  to  be 
paid.  We  shall  send  in  these  proposals  in  proper  form. " — Amalgamated  Engineers' 
Monthly  Journal,  April  1897. 


The  Right  to  a  Trade  525 

dispute  was  of  little  consequence,  the  officials  of  the  federated 
workmen  and  the  associated  employers  would  quickly  arrive 
at  an  agreed  rate.  When,  as  in  the  more  difficult  case  of 
a  laborer  being  put  to  work  a  new  machine,  the  rates 
widely  diverged,  the  agreement  would  involve  a  longer 
bargaining.  The  representative  of  the  associated  employers 
would  try  to  adduce  evidence  that  the  work  was  within  the 
capacity  of  any  general  laborer  fetched  out  of  the  street, 
and  was  therefore  only  worth  sixpence  an  hour.  The  repre- 
sentative of  the  federated  Trade  Unionists  would  seek  to 
establish  that  the  work  really  required  an  engineer's  skill  or 
training,  and  that  the  particular  laborer  employed  happened 
to  be  an  exceptional  man,  who  ought  to  be  earning  the 
engineer's  rate  of  tenpence  an  hour.  The  advocates  on  both 
sides,  representing  great  federations  of  which  the  actual  dis- 
putants formed  an  infinitesimal  proportion,  would  certainly 
manage  to  agree  upon  a  rate  for  that  special  work,  rather 
than  involve  the  whole  body  of  their  clients  in  war.  Once 
the  special  rate  for  the  disputed  process  was  authoritatively 
determined,  the  individual  employer  might  engage  any  work- 
man he  pleased  at  that  rate,  whether  he  belonged  to  the 
Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers  or  to  the  humbler  United 
Association  of  Machine  Workers,  or  even  to  the  National 
Laborers'  Union.  Thus,  subject  to  the  Standard  Rate  for 
the  disputed  work  being  fixed  by  Collective  Bargaining 
between  the  associated  employers  and  the  federated  Trade 
Unions,  any  shipbuilder  would  be  at  liberty,  as  between  trade 
and  trade,  to  select  which  man  he  pleased  to  do  the  work. 

For  the  federated  Trade  Unions  there  would  remain  the 
further  question  whether,  in  the  interests  of  the  most  perfect 
organisation,  the  workman  so  selected  should  be  transferred 
from  one  union  to  another,  or  allowed  to  remain  in  his  old 
society.  If  the  job  was  only  a  temporary  one,  it  would  be 
unnecessary  to  make  any  change.  If,  on  the  other  hand, 
the  task  for  which  he  was  selected  was  habitually  performed 
by  members  of  another  union,  or  if  it  necessitated  close  com- 
panionship with  them,  it  would  probably  avoid  friction  if  he 


526  Trade  Union  Function 

were  transferred  to  the  roll  of  the  other  union.  With 
this,  however,  the  employers  would  have  nothing  to  do,  and 
the  particular  internal  regulations  decided  upon  by  the 
federation  would,  as  in  all  other  cases,  be  finally  determined 
by  its  constituents.1 

This  solution  would  not,  we  think,  be  objected  to  by 
employers  who,  like  the  great  captains  of  industry  of 
the  North -East  coast,  have  become  accustomed  to  deal- 
ing with  bodies  of  organised  workmen.  It  involves  no 
assumptions  other  than  those  to  which  they  have  long 
since  agreed.  The  rates  for  the  disputed  jobs  would  be 
settled,  as  they  are  at  present,  not  by  the  individual  em- 
ployer or  workman,  but  by  collective  agreements  made  by 
the  associated  employers.  The  only  difference  would  be 
that  instead  of  making  that  collective  agreement  with  a 
single  Trade  Union,  the  officials  of  the  associated  employers 
would  deal,  as  regards  the  disputed  jobs,  with  officials  repre- 
senting the  whole  body  of  Trade  Unionists  in  the  district. 
The  employers  would  be  freed  from  the  annoyance  of  finding 
their  works  stopped  by  the  men's  quarrels,  and  they  would 
be  confirmed  in  their  freedom  to  allot  their  jobs  in  the  way 
they  thought  best. 

The  Trade  Unionists,  on  the  other  hand,  would  secure 
their  fundamental  principle  of  maintaining  the  Standard 
Rate  and  all  the  machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining.  They 
would  gain  complete  protection  against  any  attempt  to  make 
the  introduction  of  a  new  machine  or  a  new  product  an 

1  In  making  these  transfers  of  particular  workmen  from  union  to  union,  a 
difficulty  might  arise  from  the  difference  in  rates  of  contribution  and  scales  of 
benefit  between  different  societies.  This  could  easily  be  surmounted,  as  regards 
the  workman,  by  the  new  society  admitting  him  at  once  to  full  benefits,  accord- 
ing to  his  length  of  membership  in  the  union  he  leaves.  Mutual  arrangements  of 
this  sort  already  exist  for  the  transfer  of  members  between  Scottish  and  English 
unions  in  the  same  trade,  and  some  others.  If  the  unions  giving  large  benefits 
demurred  to  accepting  members  on  these  terms,  it  would  be  easy  for  the  Federa- 
tion to  smooth  the  way  by  giving  from  federal  funds,  in  respect  of  each  man 
officially  transferred  on  demarcation  grounds,  a  sum  equal  to  the  accumulated 
balance  per  member  possessed  by  his  new  colleagues.  Any  such  question  of 
financial  adjustment  between  union  and  union  would  easily  be  settled  by  the 
practical  good  sense  of  Trade  Union  officials. 


The  Right  to  a  Trade  527 

excuse  for  lowering  the  rate  hitherto  paid  for  a  particular 
grade  of  skill.  On  the  other  hand,  they  would  have  frankly 
to  abandon  the  obsolete  doctrine  of  a  "right  to  a  trade." 
They  would  have  to  allow  each  individual  employer  com- 
plete freedom,  provided  that  he  paid  the  Standard  Rates 
agreed  upon  for  the  various  kinds  of  work,  to  allot  them 
among  the  trades  as  he  found  most  convenient,  irrespective 
of  past  custom.  And  if  the  Trade  Unions  wished  to  avoid 
friction  among  the  workmen,  and  perfect  their  organisation, 
they  would  have  to  give  up  all  idea  of  restricting  the  entrance 
into  the  several  unions,  otherwise  than  by  requiring  their 
recruits  to  be  able  to  earn  the  recognised  Standard  Rate. 
In  both  cases,  as  this  and  the  preceding  chapter  will  have 
shown,  they  would  only  be  giving  up  a  principle  which  the 
vast  majority  of  unions,  over  the  greater  part  of  the  field  of 
British  industry,  have  found  it  impossible  to  carry  out. 


CHAPTER    XII 

THE   IMPLICATIONS    OF   TRADE   UNIONISM 

IN  the  preceding  chapters  we  have  attempted  systematically 
to  analyse  all  the  current  regulations  of  British  Trade 
Unionism ;  we  have  still  to  set  forth  and  explain  certain 
features  of  Trade  Union  policy  which  are  implied  in  the  use 
of  its  Methods  or  are  subsidiary  to  the  enforcement  of  its 
Regulations. 

We  will  begin  with  the  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance. 
We  have  seen  how  important  a  part  is  played,  except  in  a 
few  industries,  by  the  friendly  society  side  of  Trade  Unionism 
— how  it  supplies  both  adventitious  attraction  and  adven- 
titious support  to  the  workmen's  combinations,  even  when  its 
use  as  a  separate  method  of  enforcing  common  rules  has  faded 
out  of  sight.  Trade  Unionists  are  proud  of  the  great  insur- 
ance societies  which  have  been  built  up  by  their  own  efforts, 
and  most  determinedly  oppose  any  project  which  seems 
inimical  to  their  continued  prosperity.  This  affords  an 
explanation  of  the  deadweight  of  silent  opposition  which 
the  Trade  Unions  have  hitherto  thrown  against  all  compet- 
ing schemes  of  insurance.  When  the  rival  project  is  an 
employer's  benefit  society,  the  Trade  Unionists  object  to  it 
for  many  additional  reasons,  with  which  we  shall  deal  in  a 
subsequent  part  of  this  chapter.  But  even  when  an  insur- 
ance project  is  quite  unconnected  with  industrial  objects, 
and  takes  the  impersonal  form  of  a  Government  Old  Age 
Pension  scheme,  the  Trade  Unionists  strenuously  object  to 


The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism          529 

any  premium  to  be  levied  by  way  of  deduction  from  their 
weekly  earnings  or  other  form  of  direct  contribution,  which 
would,  it  is  feared,  make  the  workmen  less  ready  to  subscribe 
to  a  trade  friendly  society.  We  find  this  feeling  clearly 
expressed  in  Mr.  Broadhurst's  Minority  Report  in  the  Aged 
Poor  Commission  of  1895.  "The  evidence  tendered  by 
working  class  witnesses  goes,  in  my  opinion,  to  show  that 
any  scheme  involving  contributions,  otherwise  than  through 
the  rates  and  taxes,  would  meet  with  much  opposition  from 
the  wage -earners  of  every  grade.  The  Friendly  Societies 
and  the  Trade  Unions,  to  which  the  working  class  owe  so 
much,  naturally  view  with  some  apprehension  the  creation 
of  a  gigantic  rival  insurance  society  backed  by  the  whole 
power  of  the  Government.  The  collection  of  contributions 
from  millions  of  ill-paid  households  is  already  found  to  be 
a  task  of  great  difficulty,  intensified  by  every  depression  of 
trade  or  other  calamity.  For  the  State  to  enter  into  com- 
petition for  the  available  subscriptions  of  the  wage-earners 
must  necessarily  increase  the  difficulty  of  all  Friendly 
Societies,  Trade  Unions,  and  Industrial  Insurance  Companies, 
whose  members  and  customers  within  the  United  Kingdom 
probably  number,  in  the  aggregate,  from  eleven  to  twelve 
millions  of  persons.  On  the  other  hand,  Mr.  Charles  Booth's 
proposal  for  the  grant  of  a  pension  from  public  funds,  without 
personal  contributions,  may  secure  the  hearty  support  both 
of  the  Trade  Unions  and  the  Friendly  Societies."1 

So  far  the  Trade  Unions  stand  shoulder  to  shoulder  with 
the  ordinary  friendly  societies.  But  when  it  comes  to  defin- 
ing the  legal  status  of  the  two  forms  of  combination,  they  at 
once  part  company.  The  friendly  societies,  confining  them- 

1  Minority  Report  of  Mr.  Henry  Broadhurst,  M.P.  (Friendly  Society  of 
Operative  Stonemasons),  in  Report  of  the  Royal  Commission  on  Aged  Poor 
(C.  7604),  1895,  p.  xcix. 

This  hostility  is  naturally  most  marked  among  members  of  the  great  trade 
friendly  societies.  The  coalminers,  who  make  practically  no  use  of  friendly 
benefits  in  their  Trade  Unionism,  have  always  shown  themselves  willing  to 
encourage  the  Permanent  Relief  Funds,  through  which,  by  the  joint  subscriptions 
of  employers  and  employed,  provision  is  now  made  for  the  sufferers  from  accident 
within  the  limits  of  a  given  coalfield. 

VOL.  II  2  M 


53O  Trade  Union  Function 

selves  strictly  to  one  definite  function,  have  obtained  the 
privilege,  on  registration  of  their  rules  and  submission  of 
their  accounts,  of  becoming  legally  incorporated  bodies,  able 
to  enter  into  enforcible  contracts  with  their  members  and 
outsiders,  and  to  sue  or  be  sued  in  their  corporate  capacity. 
Such  complete  legalisation  does  not  suit  the  great  trade 
societies.  Some  measure  of  incorporation  they  must  have, 
in  order  that  the  money  subscribed  by  all  alike  may  not, 
with  impunity,  be  embezzled  by  those  in  whose  hands  it  is 
placed.  But  the  whole  friendly  society  business  of  a  Trade 
Union  is,  as  we  have  seen  in  the  chapter  on  "  The  Method  of 
Mutual  Insurance,"  only  an  adventitious  adjunct,  strictly  sub- 
ordinate to  its  main  function  of  securing,  for  its  members, 
better  conditions  of  employment.  In  pursuit  of  these  better 
conditions  the  Trade  Union  must  be  free,  in  any  emergency, 
to  use  every  penny  of  its  funds  in  the  fight.  It  does  not 
therefore  undertake  to  maintain  all  or  any  of  its  benefits,  if  a 
majority  of  the  members  for  the  time  being  wish  the  cash  in 
hand  to  be  applied  to  other  purposes.  Moreover,  it  is,  as  we 
explained  in  the  chapter  on  "  The  Method  of  Collective  Bar- 
gaining," an  essential  condition  of  Trade  Union  action  that 
the  decision  of  the  great  mass  of  the  members  should  be 
enforced  on  individual  recalcitrants.  A  member  who  persists 
in  acting  in  flagrant  disobedience  to  the  rules  of  the  associa- 
tion he  has  joined,  whether  they  relate  to  friendly  benefits 
or  not,  must  eventually  incur  the  penalty  of  expulsion,  in- 
volving the  forfeiture  of  all  claim  to  future  benefit.  A  Trade 
Union  would  therefore  be  fatally  hampered  if  it  entered  into 
legally  binding  contracts  to  pay  particular  benefits,  or  if  it 
were  possible  for  an  aggrieved  member  to  appeal,  against 
the  decision  of  his  fellow-members,  to  the  unfriendly  courts 
of  justice.  But  this  inimical  action  of  discontented  members 
is  not  the  whole  danger.  Though  combination  in  restraint 
of  trade  is  no  longer  a  criminal  offence,  it  may  still,  as  we 
shall  see,  be  made  the  ground  of  a  civil  action  for  damages.1 
The  indefinite  and  anomalous  state  of  the  law  with  regard 

1   See  the  Appendix  on  "The  Legal  Position  of  Collective  Bargaining." 


The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism          53  i 

to  libel  and  conspiracy  leaves  open,  too,  a  wide  door  for 
harassing  proceedings.  Already,  any  agent  or  official  of  a 
Trade  Union  is  liable  to  be  sued  by  an  employer  or  non- 
unionist  workman,  whenever  the  Trade  Union  action  has, 
through  him,  caused  loss  or  damage.  If  the  Trade  Union 
could  be  sued  in  its  corporate  capacity,  the  members  would 
quickly  find  the  funds  which  they  had  subscribed  for  sick 
and  funeral  benefits,  attached  at  the  suit  of  employers 
aggrieved  by  a  threat  to  strike,  by  the  libel  of  an  injudicious 
branch  secretary,  or  by  the  insolence  of  a  picket.  Thus, 
whilst  complete  incorporation  might  protect  the  individual 
member  against  a  majority  of  his  fellows,  it  would  put  his 
provision  for  sickness  and  old  age  at  the  mercy  of  employers' 
claims  for  damages.  The  insecurity  of  the  friendly  society 
side  of  Trade  Unionism  is,  in  fact,  inherent  in  the  conjunc- 
tion of  trade  and  friendly  purposes,  and  complete  legalisation 
would  actually  diminish,  rather  than  increase,  the  likelihood 
of  the  funds  subscribed  for  friendly  benefits  being  ultimately 
applied  to  meet  them. 

These  considerations  explain  the  peculiar  legal  status 
which  the  Trade  Unionists  of  1868-71  succeeded  in  winning 
for  their  associations.  The  Trade  Union  Act  of  1871,  whilst 
giving  a  duly  registered  union  much  the  same  status  as  a 
friendly  society  so  far  as  the  protection  of  its  property  was 
concerned,  expressly  provided  that  a  Trade  Union  should 
not  be  able  to  sue,  nor  be  liable  to  be  sued,  in  respect  of 
any  agreement  between  itself  and  its  members,  or  with  an 
employers'  association  or  another  union.  Trade  Unions,  in 
fact,  have  not  been  clothed  with  legal  personality  any  further 
than  for  the  limited  purpose  of  protecting  their  funds  against 
theft  or  embezzlement.  They  are  thus  in  the  anomalous 
position,  to  quote  the  Majority  Report  of  the  Labor  Com- 
mission, of  exercising  "  collective  action  without  legal  col- 
lective responsibility." *  This  peculiar  status  the  Trade 
Unionists  wish  to  maintain.  The  Trade  Union  Minority  of 

1  Fifth  and  Final  Report  of  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor \  1894  (C.  7421), 
par.  149,  p.  54. 


532  Trade  Union  Function 

the  Labor  Commission  resolutely  refused  to  entertain  the 
suggestion  "  that  it  would  be  desirable  to  make  Trade 
Unions  liable  to  be  sued  by  any  person  who  had  a  grievance 
against  the  action  of  their  officers  or  agents.  To  expose 
the  large  amalgamated  societies  of  the  country  with  their 
accumulated  funds  sometimes  reaching  a  quarter  of  a  million 
sterling,  to  be  sued  for  damages  by  any  employer  in  any 
part  of  the  country,  or  by  any  discontented  member  or  non- 
unionist,  for  the  action  of  some  branch  secretary  or  delegate, 
would  be  a  great  injustice.  If  every  Trade  Union  were 
liable  to  be  perpetually  harassed  by  actions  at  law  on 
account  of  the  doings  of  individual  members ;  if  Trade 
Union  funds  were  to  be  depleted  by  lawyers'  fees  and  costs, 
if  not  even  by  damages  or  fines,  it  would  go  far  to  make 
Trade  Unionism  impossible  for  any  but  the  most  prosperous 
and  experienced  artisans.  The  present  freedom  of  Trade 
Unions  from  any  interference  by  the  courts  of  law — anomalous 
as  it  may  appear  to  lawyers — was,  after  prolonged  struggle 
and  Parliamentary  agitation,  conceded  in  1871,  and  finally 
became  law  in  1875.  Any-  attempt  to  revoke  this  hardly- 
won  charter  of  Trade  Union  freedom,  or  in  any  way  to 
tamper  with  the  purely  voluntary  character  of  their  associa- 
tions, would,  in  our  opinion,  provoke  the  most  embittered 
resistance  from  the  whole  body  of  Trade  Unionists,  and 
would,  we  think,  be  undesirable  from  every  point  of  view." l 

Passing  now  to  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining,  we 
notice,  in  the  first  place,  that  it  implies  the  removal  of  all 
legal  prohibition  of  combination  "  in  restraint  of  trade."  So 
long  as  trade  combination  was  a  criminal  offence,  the  Method 
of  Collective  Bargaining  was  not  open  either  to  employers  or 
to  workmen,  and  Trade  Unionists,  when  they  could  not  get 
legislation,  had  to  resort  to  secret  compacts  among  them- 
selves, resting  on  the  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance.  Free- 
dom of  combination  is  now  professedly  conceded,  so  far  as 
the  criminal  law  is  concerned,  but  even  in  England  there  are 

1  Fifth  and  Final  Report  of  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor ;  1894  (C.  7421), 
p.  146. 


The  Implications  of  l^rade  Unionism          533 

signs,  as  will  be  seen  from  our  appendix  on  the  Legal  Position 
of  Collective  Bargaining,  that,  as  regards  civil  liability,  Trade 
Unionists  have  still  a  battle  to  fight.  If  the  recent  decisions 
are  upheld,  the  employers  will  be  able  to  proceed  for  heavy 
damages  against  any  Trade  Union  official  who  uses  the  ordi- 
nary arts  of  bargaining  on  behalf  of  his  constituents,  or 
who  even  advises  the  workmen  of  a  particular  firm  to  refuse 
the  employer's  terms.  Every  strike  will  bring  a  shower  of 
writs,  ending  in  bankruptcy  proceedings  ;  and  Trade  Union 
executives,  finding  themselves  exposed  to  this  harassing 
persecution,  will  again  become  secret  conspiracies.  If,  there- 
fore, Collective  Bargaining  is  to  survive  as  a  method  of  Trade 
Unionism,  Parliament  will  have  to  complete  the  work  of 
1871-75,  and  definitely  instruct  the  judges  that  nothing  is 
to  be  actionable  in  labor  disputes  when  done  by  or  in 
pursuance  of  a  combination  of  workmen,  which  would  not 
be  actionable  if  done  by  a  partnership  of  traders  as  part  of 
their  business,  and  in  the  pursuit  of  their  personal  gain. 

But  the  workman's  freedom  of  contract,  and,  still  more, 
his  freedom  of  combination,  necessarily  involves,  as  we  have 
seen,  his  freedom  to  stipulate  with  whom  he  will  consent 
to  associate  in  his  labor.  This  liberty  to  refuse  to  accept 
engagements  in  establishments  where  non-unionists  are 
employed,  is,  in  such  highly-organised  trades  as  the  North- 
umberland Coalminers  or  the  Lancashire  Cotton-spinners, 
tantamount  to  compulsory  Trade  Unionism.  And  wherever 
Collective  Bargaining  is  perfected  by  such  formal  machinery 
as  the  Joint  Boards  or  Joint  Committees  of  the  North  of 
England  Manufactured  Iron  Trade,  or  the  Northumberland 
and  Durham  Miners,  or  by  such  national  treaties  as  those 
regulating  the  wages  and  other  conditions  of  labor  of  the 
Boilermakers,  hand  Papermakers,  and  factory  Boot  and  Shoe 
Operatives,  the  collective  regulations  become  virtually  binding 
throughout  the  whole  trade.  The  compulsion  on  the  in- 
dividual, it  need  hardly  be  said,  is  none  the  less  real  and 
effective  because  it  takes  an  impersonal,  peaceful,  and  entirely 
decorous  form.  A  plater  or  rivetter  who,  because  he  is  out* 


534  Trade  Union  Function 

side  the  United  Society  of  Boilermakers,  is  politely  refused 
work  by  every  shipbuilder  on  the  North-East  coast,  is  just 
as  much  compelled  to  join  the  union,  as  if  membership  were, 
by  a  new  Factory  Act,  made  a  legal  condition  of  employment. 
Collective  Bargaining  thus  implies,  in  its  fullest  develop- 
ment, compulsory  Trade  Unionism.  It  was  the  recognition 
of  this  fact  which  led  to  the  remarkable  proposal  of  the  Duke 
of  Devonshire,  and  some  of  the  most  eminent  of  his  colleagues 
on  the  Labor  Commission,  to  enable  Trade  Unions  to  enter 
into  legally  binding  collective  agreements  on  behalf  of  all 
their  members.  The  great  employers  of  the  North  of  England 
find  that  there  is,  in  their  highly  -  organised  industries, 
practically  no  non-unionist  minority  which  they  can  play  off 
against  the  Trade  Union,  whose  officials  therefore  virtually 
speak  in  the  name  of  all  the  available  workmen.  On  the 
other  hand,  they  have  no  guarantee  that  individual  branches 
or  members  will  loyally  abide  by  the  collective  agreement 
when  it  is  made.  It  was  therefore  proposed,  by  five  of  the 
largest  employers  of  labor  on  the  Commission,1  that  when  a 
collective  agreement  had  been  made  between  a  Trade  Union 
and  an  Employers'  Association,  these  bodies  should  be,  in  their 
corporate  capacities,  responsible  in  damages  for  any  breach 
by  their  members,  and  should  be  entitled,  on  the  other  hand, 
to  recover  such  damages  from  the  individuals  who  had  in- 
fringed the  treaty.  This  suggestion  was,  as  we  have  mentioned, 
vehemently  objected  to  by  the  Trade  Unionists,  because  it 

1  See  the  "Observations  appended  to  the  Report"  (C.  7421),  pp.  115-119. 
These  were  signed,  not  only  by  the  Duke  of  Devonshire  (himself  a  great  employer 
of  labor  in  many  industrial  undertakings),  but  also  by  Sir  David  Dale  of  Darling- 
ton (Ironmaster  and  Coalowner),  Mr.  Thomas  Ismay  (Shipowner),  Mr.  George 
Livesey  (Gas  Company  Director),  and  Mr.  William  Tunstill  (Railway  Director). 
They  also  gained  the  support  of  Sir  Michael  Hicks-Beach,  Mr.  Leonard  Courtney, 
and  Sir  Frederick  Pollock.  This  proposal  has  more  than  once  received  the 
approval  of  the  Times.  Thus,  in  a  leading  article  of  the  loth  June  1897,  relating 
to  the  progress  of  the  Trade  Unions,  it  observed  that  "at  present,  though  freed 
from  the  most  serious  of  the  disabilities  under  which  they  once  labored,  they 
have  no  true  corporate  existence  ;  they  cannot  make  enforceable  contracts  ;  they 
can  bind,  broadly  speaking,  their  members  to  nothing.  One  of  the  few  practical 
suggestions  which  emerged  from  the  stream  of  loose  talk  passing  through  the  Labor 
Commission  was  a  proposal  that  this  should  be  altered — a  proposal  which  found 
favor  with  some  of  the  most  sober-minded  of  the  members  of  the  Commission." 


The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism          535 

was  incidentally  intended  to  give  the  Trade  Union  a  legal 
personality,  which  would  render  it  liable  to  be  sued  in  the 
law  courts  by  any  disaffected  member  or  aggrieved  outsider. 
So  sweeping  a  change  in  Trade  Union  status  was,  how- 
ever, not  necessary  for  the  Duke  of  Devonshire's  proposal. 
His  object  would  have  been  secured  if  it  had  been  provided 
that  the  Trade  Union  should  be  liable  to  be  sued  only  in 
respect  of  collective  agreements  made  with  the  Employers' 
Association,  and  then  only  for  definite  penalties  specified  in 
such  agreements.  To  this  definitely  restricted  liability  no 
Trade  Union  need  object,  provided  that  it  were  given,  as  was 
contemplated,  the  corresponding  right  to  recover  the  penalty 
from  its  members  in  default,  and  provided  that  the  Employers' 
Association  were  made  reciprocally  responsible  to  the  Trade 
Union  for  the  defaults  of  particular  employers. 

Any  such  legal  enforcement  of  collective  agreements  as 
was  proposed  by  the  Duke  of  Devonshire  and  his  colleagues 
would,  of  course,  greatly  encourage  the  use  of  Collective 
Bargaining  as  a  Method  of  Trade  Unionism.  It  was,  in 
fact,  expressly  with  the  view  of  facilitating  this  "  substitution 
of  agreements  between  associations  for  agreements  between 
individual  employers  and  individual  workmen,"  which  the 
Commissioners  had  found  to  be  "  on  the  whole,  in  accordance 
with  the  public  interest,"  that  so  momentous  a  change  was 
proposed.  Trade  Unionists  would  entirely  agree  that  it 
would  "  result  in  the  better  observance,  for  definite  periods, 
of  agreements  with  regard  to  wage-rates,  hours  of  labor, 
apprenticeship  rules,  demarcation  of  work,  profit-sharing,  and 
joint  insurance  schemes."  In  all  but  the  best  organised 
industries,  the  workmen's  difficulty  is,  not  so  much  to  get 
better  terms  granted,  as  to  get  them  adhered  to.  Such 
grievously  oppressed  trades  as  the  bakers,  the  tramwaymen, 
the  dock  laborers,  and  almost  any  section  of  women  workers, 
may  often,  by  a  sensational  strike,  and  the  support  of  public 
opinion,  secure  an  agreement  promising  better  conditions 
of  employment.  But  the  day  after  the  agreement  is  signed 
it  begins  to  crumble  away.  One  employer  after  another 


536  Trade  Union  Function 

"  interprets "  it  in  his  own  fashion,  and  the  workers  in  his 
establishment,  no  longer  upheld  by  the  excitement  of  a 
general  strike,  and  frequently  not  precisely  understanding 
what  is  happening,  are  induced  to  acquiesce  by  fear  of  losing 
their  employment,  if  not  by  actual  threats  of  dismissal.  If 
the  Trade  Union  could  sue  any  such  employer  for  damages 
for  breaking  the  collective  agreement,  its  terms  would,  for  the 
time  being,  become,  in  effect,  part  of  the  law  of  the  land. 
The  highly -organised  trades  would  find  their  advantage 
rather  in  the  direction  of  improved  discipline  among  their 
own  members.  Until  the  expiration  of  the  collective  agree- 
ment at  any  rate,  a  recalcitrant  minority  would  find  itself 
confronted,  not  only  by  the  displeasure  of  the  majority,  but 
also  by  all  the  terrors  of  the  law  courts.1  Any  such  arrange- 
ment would  therefore  greatly  strengthen  the  influence  of  the 
Trade  Union  as  a  whole,  and  would,  in  all  industries,  tend 
enormously  to  the  development  of  such  an  expert  Trade 
Union  Civil  Service  as  is  already  enjoyed  by  the  Cotton 
Operatives.  Whether  this  addition  to  the  compulsory 
character  of  Collective  Bargaining  would  prove  as  harmless 
to  the  consumers  as  it  would  to  the  great  employers  ;  whether, 
to  use  the  phrase  of  Mr.  Gerald  Balfour,  M.P.,  the  Duke  of 
Devonshire's  "  Socialism  by  Trade  Option  "  is  a  safe  kind  of 
Socialism  for  the  community  to  establish  ;  affords  an  interest- 
ing problem  for  consideration  by  economists  and  statesmen. 
The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  has  implications  of  its 
own,  which  compel  us  to  touch  on  the  wider  question  of  the 
part  taken  by  the  Trade  Unionists  in  the  party  struggles  of 
politics.  We  have  already  described  how  Mutual  Insurance 
and  Collective  Bargaining  depend  on  the  legal  status  of  the 
Trade  Unions.  Freedom  of  combination,  protection  for 

1  If  a  Trade  Union  were  made  liable  for  the  observance  of  the  agreement  for 
a  definite  period,  it  is  obvious  that  no  member  of  the  union  could  be  permitted 
to  withdraw  for  that  period,  at  any  rate  so  far  as  concerns  observing  the  agreement 
and  contributing  towards  its  expenses.  Thus,  Trade  Union  membership  would 
become,  in  effect,  not  only  universally  compulsory,  but  also  irrevocable  for  a  long 
term.  The  same  would  be  the  case  with  regard  to  membership  of  an  employers' 
association. 


The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism          537 

Trade  Union  funds,  and  liberty  to  strike  have  not  been 
gained  without  political  conflicts,  in  which  the  Trade  Unionists 
have  had  to  use  every  means  of  influencing  the  legislature. 
But  these  questions  have  involved  only  certain  definite  legal 
reforms,  outside  the  scope  of  party  politics  ;  and  they  could, 
once  Parliament  was  convinced,  be  finally  disposed  of.  It 
is  only  in  connection  with  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment 
that  the  Trade  Unions,  as  such,  find  it  necessary  to  secure  a 
permanent  influence  in  the  House  of  Commons.  Every  year 
one  section  or  another  calls  for  new  regulations  to  be  passed 
into  law,  in  the  form  of  an  amendment  of  the  Factory  or  Mines, 
Railway  or  Merchant  Shipping  Acts.  The  administration  of 
these  statutes  requires  constant  supervision,  which  can  only 
be  effectively  exercised  from  the  House  of  Commons.  And 
with  the  growth  of  the  public  administration  of  industry, 
whether  central  or  local,  the  Trade  Unions  consider  it 
essential  that  they  should  be  in  a  position  to  secure  the  strict 
observance  of  the  standard  conditions  by  the  national  and 
municipal  employers  of  labor. 

It  was,  therefore,  a  vital  political  necessity  that  the  Trade 
Unionists  should  obtain  complete  electoral  rights.  From  1831 
to  1884  the  banners  of  the  Unions  always  appeared  at  the 
great  demonstrations  in  favor  of  Parliamentary  Reform.  The 
whole  strength  of  the  Trade  Union  movement  was  thrown 
on  the  side  of  the  ballot,  the  removal  of  tests  and  property 
qualifications,  and  everything  that  promised  to  facilitate  the 
expression  of  Trade  Union  views  in  Parliament  and  on  local 
bodies.  Thus,  between  1860  and  1885,  when  the  Liberal 
Party  was  striving  for  extensions  of  the  franchise,  and  the 
Conservative  Party  was,  with  the  exception  of  a  few  months 
in  the  session  of  1867,  fiercely  resisting  reform,  the  Liberal 
leaders  could  count  on  the  adhesion  of  the  great  bulk  of  the 
Trade  Unionists.  During  these  years  every  prominent  Trade 
Union  official  belonged  to  the  Radical  Wing  of  the  Liberal 
Party.1 

1  The  revulsion  of  feeling  between  1871  and  1874,  caused  by  the  incredible 
stupidity  of  the  Liberal  Cabinet  of  those  years  in  connection   with   the  criminal 


538  Trade  Union  Function 

But  this  alliance  with  the  Liberal  Party  has  proved  only 
temporary.  The  completion  of  electoral  reform  has.  since 
1885,  fallen  into  the  background,  the  Liberal  leaders  being 
indifferent,  if  not  actually  hostile,  to  the  Trade  Union 
demands  for  Manhood  Suffrage,  Payment  of  Members,  and 
Payment  of  Election  Expenses,  whilst  the  lukewarm  official 
proposals  for  Registration  Reform  have  evoked  no  enthusiasm. 
Trade  Union  politics  have  therefore  entered  on  a  new  phase. 
The  Trade  Unionists,  having  obtained  the  vote,  now  wish  to 
make  use  of  it  to  enforce,  by  Legal  Enactment,  such  of  their 
Common  Rules  as  they  see  a  chance  of  getting  public  opinion 
to  support.  Here  they  find  themselves  almost  equally 
balanced  between  the  claims  of  rival  political  parties.  Judged 
by  past  performances,  the  Conservatives  are  less  un- 
sympathetic to  the  legal  regulation  of  industry  than  the 
Liberals  ;  whilst  the  Workmen's  Compensation  Act  of  1897 
has  placed  the  Trade  Unionists  under  a  fresh  obligation  to 
the  Conservative  Party.  On  the  other  hand,  the  Collectivist 
wing  of  the  present  Liberal  Party  is  beginning,  by  pro- 
fessions of  conversion  from  "  Manchesterism,"  and  large  pro- 
mises of  future  legislation,  to  make  a  special  bid  for  Trade 
Union  support.  The  leaders  on  both  sides  are  candidly 
hostile  to  the  principle  of  collective  regulation,  and  the 
Yorkshire  Coalminer  or  Lancashire  Cotton -spinner  may 
ivell  doubt  whether  Sir  William  Harcourt  and  Mr.  John 
Morley  are  any  nearer  in  agreement  with  him  than  Mr. 
Balfour  or  Mr.  Chamberlain.  Meanwhile  a  third  party 
has  arisen,  to  point  the  moral  and  compete  for  the  workmen's 
suffrages.  The  Socialist  candidates  are  ready  to  promise 

persecution  of  Trade  Unionism,  led,  as  we  have  described  in  our  History  of  Trade 
Unionism  (pp.  256-280),  to  an  organised  revolt,  to  independent  candidatures, 
and  to  a  certain  transference  of  votes  to  progressive  Conservatives  who  agreed  to 
satisfy  the  Trade  Union  demands.  The  popular  Conservative  legislation  of 
1874-75  (the  Trade  Union  Act  and  the  "  Factories  (Health  of  Women)  Act"), 
which  embodied  a  great  measure  of  what  the  Trade  Unionists  had  been  asking  for, 
no  doubt  detached  a  large  section  of  workmen  from  their  alliance  with  Liberalism, 
especially  in  Lancashire.  But  so  strong  was  the  impulse  towards  an  extension  of 
the  franchise  that  the  leaders,  even  in  Lancashire,  made  up  their  quarrel  with  the 
Liberal  Party,  and  acted  with  it  until  the  Reform  Bills  of  1884-85  were  safely 
passed  into  law. 


The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism          539 

the  Trade  Unionists  a  systematic  and  complete  regulation  of 
all  the  conditions  of  employment.  But  they  show  a  lament- 
able deficiency  of  technical  knowledge  of  the  exact  regula- 
tions required,  and  they  mingle  their  proposals  with 
revolutionary  Shibboleths  as  to  the  "  nationalisation  of  the 
means  of  production,  distribution,  and  exchange,"  which  the 
bulk  of  the  Trade  Unionists  fail  even  to  comprehend. 
Accordingly,  the  strong  desire  of  nearly  all  sections  of  Trade 
Unionists  for  this  or  that  measure  of  legal  enactment  does 
not  at  present  produce  much  effect  on  general  politics. 
Unlike  their  demand  for  the  franchise,  it  does  not,  for  the 
moment,  attach  them,  as  Trade  Unionists,  to  any  political 
party.  But  it  implies  that  they  would  be  strongly,  and  even 
permanently,  drawn  to  any  political  leader,  of  whatever  party, 
who  shared  their  faith  in  the  efficacy  of  the  Common  Rule, 
and  who  convinced  them  that  he  had  the  technical  know- 
ledge, the  will,  and  the  Parliamentary  power  to  carry  into 
law  such  proposals  for  legal  regulation  as  each  trade  from 
time  to  time  definitely  demanded. 

If  now  we  leave  the  Methods  of  Trade  Unionism,  and 
pass  to  its  Regulations,  we  shall  see  that  these,  too,  have 
their  own  implications,  and  that  Trade  Unionists  oppose  or 
accept  certain  industrial  forms  according  as  these  appear  to 
be  inimical  to  Trade  Union  progress,  or  the  reverse.  Fore- 
most among  these  implications  is  the  strong  Trade  Union 
objection  to  "  Home  Work,"  that  is,  to  work  being  given  out 
by  the  employer,  to  be  done  elsewhere  than  in  the  factory 
or  workshop  which  he  provides.1  In  all  the  industries  in 
which  "  out-working  "  prevails  to  any  considerable  extent,  this 

1  Under  this  head  we  include  all  arrangements  under  which  the  manual- 
working  wage-earner  performs  his  task  elsewhere  than  in  a  factory  or  workshop 
provided  and  controlled  by  his  employer.  The  term  "  home  work  "  is  sometimes 
used  to  designate  only  work  taken  home  by  factory  workers  after  the  expiration 
of  their  factory  day  (see  Home  Work  amongst  Women,  by  Margaret  H.  Irwin, 
Glasgow,  1897).  On  the  other  hand,  the  "outworker"  may  not  work  in  his 
own  home,  but  (as  at  Sheffield)  on  a  "wheel"  or  "trough"  rented  in  a  "tene- 
ment factory,"  or  (as  sometimes  among  the  Scottish  hand  Shoemakers)  in  a 
co-operative  workshop  rented  by  a  group  of  workmen  or  by  the  Trade  Union 
itself. 


540  Trade  Union  Fimction 

objection,  steadily  growing  in  intensity  for  the  last  half- 
century,  has  latterly  risen  into  a  crusade.  The  National 
Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  J  and  the  Scottish  Tailors' 
Society  now  put  the  complete  abolition  of  home  work  in  the 
front  of  their  programme.  The  English  Tailors'  Union, 
though  it  includes  home  workers,  is  scarcely  less  emphatic. 
"  If,"  reports  the  General  Secretary,  "  we  cannot  altogether 
abolish  this  curse  we  can  at  least  prevent  its  growth,  and 
wherever  there  is  the  slightest  sign  of  the  system  being 
introduced  into  towns  where  it  has  hitherto  been  unknown, 
it  is  our  duty  not  to  tolerate  it  for  a  single  minute,  but  use 
our  utmost  endeavors  to  oppose  its  introduction,  and 
stamp  it  out  as  far  as  lies  in  our  power  in  all  places  where  it 
at  present  exists."  2 

This  vehement  objection  to  home  work  comes  as  a 
surprise  to  persons  unfamiliar  with  the  actual  conditions  of 
the  wage-earner's  existence.  One  of  the  principal  grievances 
that  Trade  Unions  are  formed  to  remedy  is,  as  we  have  seen, 
the  autocratic  manner  in  which  the  employer,  in  any  unregu- 
lated trade,  determines  at  what  hours  his  workshop  will  open 
and  close,  when  his  workpeople  shall  take  their  meals  or 
enjoy  their  holidays,  how  fast  and  how  continuously  they 
shall  work,  and  a  host  of  petty  regulations,  easily  passing, 
with  a  brutal  foreman,  into  gross  personal  tyranny.  From 
all  this  the  man  or  woman  working  in  the  home  is  apparently 
free.  Once  the  work  is  taken  out  of  the  employer's  ware- 
house, the  worker  is  at  liberty  to  do  it  when  and  where  and 
how  he  pleases,  free  from  the  constant  supervision  and 
arbitrary  meddling  of  the  foreman.  Home  work  has,  to  the 
philanthropist,  certain  sentimental  attractions.  There  is  no 
breaking-up  of  family  life.  Husband  and  wife  can  work  side 

1  The  National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  puts  high  up  among  its 
objects  the  "establishment  of  healthy  and  proper  workshops,  the  employers  to 
find  room,  grindery,  fixtures,  fire,  and  gas  free  of  charge." — Rules  of  the  National 
Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  (Leicester,  1892). 

2  Report  of  the  Fourteenth  Conference  of  Deputies  of  the  Amalgamated  Society 
of  Tailors,  held  in   Liverpool,  August   1891    (Manchester,    1891);    Secretary's 
Report  to  the  Conference,  p.  1 7. 


The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism          541 

by  side  at  a  common  task,  whilst  the  babies  frolic  around, 
and  the  child  from  school  prepares  its  lessons  under  the 
father's  eye.  No  peremptory  factory  bell  summons  the  wife 
and  mother  from  her  housekeeping  or  family  cares.  Cook- 
ing the  dinner,  nursing  the  baby,  teaching  the  child 
apprentice — all  can  be  dovetailed  into  each  other,  and  into 
the  breadwinning  craft.  The  task  of  every  member  of  the 
household  can  be  adjusted  to  their  several  capacities,  even 
the  aged  grandfather  by  the  fireside,  and  the  school-girl  on 
her  half-holiday,  being  usefully  employed.  When  illness 
comes,  one  member  of  the  family  can  nurse  another,  whilst 
continuing  to  earn  a  subsistence.  The  custom  of  working 
at  home  seems,  in  fact,  to  combine  all  possible  advantages. 
To  personal  freedom  and  domestic  bliss,  there  is  added  the 
greatest  economy  of  time  and  the  utmost  utilisation  of 
capacity.1 

Unfortunately,  the  facts  of  the  home  worker's  life  in  no 
way  correspond  to  this  Utopian  picture.  To  take  work 
home  means,  in  the  words  of  a  boot  operative,  "  to  make 
home  miserable."2  It  is  conceivable  that  the  highly -educated 
and  well -disciplined  journalist,  barrister,  banker,  or  stock- 
broker might  find  it  pleasant  to  do  all  his  professional  work 
under  the  eyes  of  his  wife,  and  amid  the  playing  of  his  well- 
bred  children.  But  even  he  would  hardly  like  to  work,  eat, 
and  sleep,  not  to  say  also  cook  and  wash,  in  one  and  the 
same  apartment.  The  middle-class  admirer  of  home  work 
forgets  that  the  "home"  of  the  ordinary  town  wage -earner 
consists  of  one,  or,  at  most,  of  two  small  rooms,  and  that  his 
work  is  not  done  in  pen  and  ink,  but  in  leather,  cloth,  fur,  hot 
metal,  glue,  and  other  substances  involving  dirt,  smells,  and 
effluvia.  It  is  impossible  to  use,  as  a  workshop,  the  living 
room  of  a  family,  without  submitting  to  conditions  of  tem- 
perature and  atmosphere,  crowding  and  disorder,  which  are 

1  See    the    description    in    Dr.    Kuno    Frankenstein's   Der  Arbeittrschutz 
(Leipzig,  1896). 

2  Monthly  Report^   National  Union  of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives,    March 
1891. 


542  Trade  Union  Function 

destructive  to  health  and  comfort.  All  these  conditions 
make  the  workshop -home  positively  repulsive  to  father, 
mother,  and  children  alike,  and  every  opportunity  is  sought 
of  escaping  from  it — the  man  to  the  public-house,  the  woman 
to  gossip  with  her  neighbours,  and  the  children  to  the 
streets.1  Instead  of  maintaining  the  integrity  of  the  family, 
and  fostering  the  domestic  virtues,  it  is  accordingly  frequently 
asserted  by  the  most  experienced  observers  that  no  influence 
is  at  the  present  day  more  ruinous  than  home  work  in  its  effect 
on  family  life  and  personal  character. 

Public  opinion  is,  therefore,  for  reasons  of  sanitation, 
family  life,  and  personal  character,  tending  more  and  more 
to  deprecate  any  combination  of  the  workshop  with  the 
living-room.  What  has  influenced  the  Trade  Unionist  is 
much  more  the  discovery  that  the  custom  of  home  work  has 
a  ruinous  effect  upon  wages.  In  the  trades  in  which  this 
custom  prevails,  the  standard  earnings  of  the  home  workers 
are  far  below  the  wage  customary  for  equally  skilled  labor 

1  Some  glimpse  of  what  home  work  implies  even  to  a  man  of  very  exceptional 
character,  is  afforded  by  the  following  extract  from  the  Autobiography  of  Francis 
Place.  (See  the  History  of  Trade  Unionism^  chap,  ii.)  "  The  consequences  of  a 
man  and  his  wife  living  in  the  same  room  in  which  the  man  works  is  mischievous 
to  them  in  all  respects,  and  I  here  add,  as  a  recommendation  to  all  journeymen, 
tradesmen,  and  other  workmen  ...  to  make  almost  any  sacrifice  to  keep 
possession  of  two  rooms,  however  small  and  however  inconveniently  situated  as 
regards  the  place  of  their  employment.  Much  better  is  it  to  be  compelled  to 
walk  a  mile  or  even  two  miles  to  and  from  their  work  to  a  lodging  with  two 
rooms,  than  to  live  close  to  their  work  with  one  room.  ...  A  neat  clean  room, 
though  it  be  as  small  as  a  closet,  and  however  few  the  articles  of  furniture,  is  of 
more  importance  in  its  moral  consequences  than  any  one  seems  hitherto  to  have 
supposed.  The  room  in  which  we  now  lived  was  a  front  room  at  a  baker's 
shop.  The  house  had  three  windows  in  the  front,  two  in  the  room  and  one  in 
a  large  closet  at  the  end  of  the  room.  In  this  closet  I  worked.  It  was  a  great 
accommodation  to  us  ;  it  enabled  my  wife  to  keep  the  room  in  better  order ;  it 
was  advantageous,  too,  in  its  moral  effects.  Attendance  on  the  child  was  not,  as 
it  had  been,  always  in  my  presence.  I  was  shut  out  from  seeing  the  fire  lighted, 
the  room  washed  and  cleaned,  and  the  clothes  washed  and  ironed,  as  well  as  the 
cooking.  We  frequently  went  to  bed  as  we  had  but  too  often  been  accustomed  to 
do,  with  a  wet  or  damp  floor,  and  with  wet  clothes  hanging  in  the  room.  Still  a 
great  deal  of  the  annoyance  and  too  close  an  interference  with  each  other  in  many 
disagreeable  particulars  (which  having  but  one  room  made  it  inevitable)  were 
removed — happily  removed  for  ever." — Place's  MS.  Autobiography,  quoted 
in  Labor  in  the  Longest  Reign,  by  Sidney  Webb  (London,  1897) ;  now  included 
in  the  Life  of  Francis  Place  by  Graham  Wallas  (London,  1897). 


The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism          543 

in  the  factory  industries.  The  chain  and  nail  workers  in 
the  Black  Country,  the  trouser  and  "  juvenile  suit "  hands  in 
East  London,  the  garret  cabinetmakers  of  Bethnal  Green, 
the  cottage  bootmakers  of  the  Leicestershire  villages,  and 
more  noteworthy  even  than  these,  the  skilled  outwork- 
ing cutlers  of  Sheffield,  were  all  found,  by  the  House  of 
Lords'  Committee  on  the  Sweating  System  (1890),  to  be 
suffering  to  an  extent  that  could  "  hardly  be  exaggerated," 
from  "  earnings  barely  sufficient  to  sustain  existence  ;  hours 
of  labor  such  as  to  make  the  lives  of  the  workers  periods  of 
almost  ceaseless  toil,  hard  and  unlovely  to  the  last  degree  ; 
sanitary  conditions  injurious  to  the  health  of  the  persons 
employed  and  dangerous  to  the  public,"1  In  every  one  of 
the  trades  in  which  this  august  Committee  reported  that 
"  sweating "  prevailed,  the  custom  of  working  in  the 
operatives'  own  homes  was  discovered  to  exist.  To  the 
Trade  Unionist  this  close  connection  between  home  work 
and  low  wages  is  no  mere  coincidence.  Experience  shows 
that  work  given  out  to  be  done  otherwise  than  on  the 
employers'  premises  almost  invariably  becomes  the  subject 

1  Report  and  Evidence  of  the  Select  Committee  of  the  House  of  Lords  on  the 
Siveating  System  (H.  L.  62  of  1890);  see  also  "The  Lords  and  the  Sweating 
System,"  by  Beatrice  Potter  (Mrs.  Sidney  Webb)  in  Nineteenth  Century,  June 
1890;  and  the  references  given  in  Fabian  Tract,  No.  50,  "Sweating,  its  Cause 
and  Remedy." 

It  must  not  be  supposed  that  the  custom  of  "giving  out"  work  to 
be  done  in  the  workers'  own  homes  is  a  new  or  an  increasing  evil.  It  is,  on  the 
contrary,  merely  the  surviving  remnant  of  what  was  once  in  many  trades  the 
prevailing  system.  In  our  History  of  Trade  Unionism  (pp.  28,  32,  48)  we  have 
incidentally  described  its  prevalence  in  the  West  of  England  cloth  manufacture, 
in  the  hosiery  trade,  among  the  Sheffield  cutlers,  the  Spitalfields  silk-workers, 
and  the  Scottish  cotton-weavers.  In  the  early  stages  of  capitalist  industry  a 
manufactory,  as  Du  Cellier  observes  with  regard  to  France,  "was  not  the  site 
but  the  centre  of  an  industry  ;  the  manufacturer  produced  the  samples  and  designs 
.  .  .  but  had  generally  not  a  single  loom  working  in  his  own  house  "  (Histoire 
des  Classes  Laborieuses  en  France,  p.  222).  It  was  an  innovation  to  collect  a 
number  of  wage-earners  in  the  employer's  own  workshop,  where  they  worked 
under  constant  supervision,  and  could  practise  division  of  labor.  In  all 
important  industries  of  Great  Britain  this  has  now  become  the  dominant  indus- 
trial form.  It  is  where  the  two  systems  are  still  competing  with  each  other — 
where  factory  and  home  work  co-exist  and  produce  for  the  same  market — that  the 
evil  of  "  sweating"  is  at  its  worst. — Der  Arbeiterschutz,  by  Dr.  Kuno  Franken- 
stein (Leipzig,  1896),  p.  492. 


544  Trade  Union  Function 

of  isolated,  personal  bargaining  between  the  individual  wage- 
earner  and  the  capitalist  employer.  "  To  people  working 
each  in  their  own  little  shop"  writes  Mr.  John  Burnett,  "  from 
early  morning  until  late  at  night,  combination  is  above  all 
things  difficult.  .  .  .  One  man  or  one  woman  can  be  played 
off  against  another,  and  the  prices  of  labor  are  thus  subject 
to  the  daily  haggle  of  workers  competing  for  bread.  This  is 
clearly  and  unmistakably  the  result  of  the  small  workshop 
system,  which  is  undoubtedly  the  root  of  many,  if  not  all  the 
evils  from  which  the  nailworkers  suffer."1  The  same  con- 
sequences of  "  outwork  "  were  noticed  by  a  careful  observer 
of  the  Liverpool  tailors  as  long  ago  as  1860.  "The  work," 
wrote  Mr.  (now  Sir)  Godfrey  Lushington,  "  admits  of  being 
done  at  home,  and  the  operative  who  engages  himself  on 
these  terms  loses  the  benefit  of  the  check  which  the  presence 
of  his  fellows  maintains  upon  the  encroachments  of  the 
employer.  In  such  a  trade  it  must  always  be  difficult  to 
establish  united  action.  .  .  .  The  common  method  of  reduc- 
tion is  for  the  employer  to  produce  a  garment  and  say,  '  I 
had  this  made  for  IDS.  6d.,  I  cannot  pay  you  133.  6d.  for  a 
similar  article.  You  too  must  make  it  for  ics.  6d.  or  go 
elsewhere.'  The  Society  cannot  prevent  this." 2  Home 
work,  in  fact,  necessarily  involves  Individual  Bargaining, 
and  makes,  moreover,  the  enforcement  of  any  Common  Rule 
practically  impossible. 

Finally,  experience  proves  the  home  worker's  "  freedom  " 
as  to  the  hours  of  labor  to  be  delusive.  It  is  true  that  the 
Soho  tailor  can  break  off  when  he  chooses,  and  go  round  to 
the  public-house  for  a  drink  ;  or  the  woman  "  picking  peas  " 
in  a  back  alley  of  Peterborough  3  may  get  up  now  and  again 


1  Report  to  the  Board  of  Trade  on  the  Sweating  System  at  the  East   End  of 
London,  H.  C.  No.  331  of  1888. 

2  Report  of  the  Social  Science  Association  on    Trade  Societies  and  Strikes 
(London,    1860).     Article  on   the    Liverpool   Tailors   by    Mr.    (afterwards   Sir) 
Godfrey  Lushington,  who  subsequently  became  permanent  Under-Secretary  of 
State  for  the  Home  Department. 

3  One  of  the  principal  women's  industries  in  the  City  of  Peterborough  is  picking 
dried  peas  ;  sorting  by  hand  the  black  or  defective  peas  from  those  of  lighter 


of  Lords'  Committee,  "the  lives      f 
"Periods   of  a,most  ceailes     toil  -     TV 
compulsion    to   «work   _,,    '     tO'h       Thls 

hastened  by  the  eat  whthichT 
demand  that  the   product  sS 
tln>e.      It    is    one   of  the   Sf 
to  the  employers,  as  they  franl! 

Committee,  that  the  utmost  posL°T 

of  pressing  orders   fa   Unfe«ered 

normal  working  day.     To  meet 

**  "ason,"  thousands  of 
,  be  automatically 


subtle  economic 


of  ™*    can 
by  a  definite 

°f  "°Utwork" 
H°USe  °f  Lords' 
'"  the  ex«ution 
conceP«on   of  a 


thus  to 


and   to 
a"  the 


emp'°yer' 


abstract,  from  the  total  rematon  O 
advantages  of  room,  fire,   S    an 

wh,ch  would  otherwise  te  provided 
are  these  insidious  effects 

The  operatives  emp,oyed  r  «n, 

presses  have  to  submit  to  redurt  ±,  ^  ^  °"  th°  em^^ 
of  hours,  under  the  threat  of  A    *  ?nsofwages  and  extensions 
°f  Jhe   business  to  thefr  ou7Wor  ''  ^  °"  °f  "«  and  m-e 
in  fact,  makes  a    TS53S  C°mPetit-s.'     Home 
Closely  related  to  the  * 

Work  is  their  rooted 


of  both     '  ' 

»  OL. 


flour;  e 


' 


'he  outdoor  „,,„ 


2  N 


546  Trade  Union  Function 

system.  To  a  certain  section  of  social  reformers  this  seems 
incomprehensible.  The  wage-earners  are  perpetually  com- 
plaining that  they  are  deprived  of  access  to  the  means  of 
production,  and  that  rents  and  profits  are  monopolised  by  a 
relatively  small  class.  The  existence,  in  certain  industries,  of 
numerous  small  establishments  would  seem  to  afford,  at  least 
to  the  most  energetic  workmen,  an  obvious  means  of  rising 
to  the  rank  of  masters.  Yet  these  "  stepping-stones  to  higher 
things  "  are  objected  to,  not  so  much  by  the  thriftless  work- 
man, careless  of  his  future,  but  by  the  most  thoughtful  and 
experienced  Trade  Unionists,  that  is,  by  exactly  the  men 
whose  superiority  in  energy,  persistency,  and  organising 
power  might  reasonably  be  expected  to  lead  to  their 
personal  success. 

The  explanation  of  this  paradox  will  not  be  difficult  for 
those  who  appreciate  the  Trade  Union  position.  Working 
men  do  not  combine  in  order  to  assist  a  few  of  the  best 
among  their  number  to  escape  out  of  their  class,  but  for 
the  purpose  of  raising  the  class  itself.  To  some  shrewd 
economists  it  seems  even  a  misfortune  to  the  wage-earning 
class  that  they  should,  as  Professor  Marshall  observes, 
"  every  year  give  over  to  the  ranks  of  the  rich  a  great  number 
of  the  strongest  and  ablest,  the  most  enterprising  and  far- 
seeing,  the  bravest  and  the  best  of  those  who  were  born 
among  themselves."  l  "  What  is  really  important  for  working 
men,"  says  Dr.  J.  K.  Ingram,  "is,  not  that  a  few  should  rise 
out  of  their  class — this  sometimes  rather  injures  the  class  by 
depriving  it  of  its  more  energetic  members.  The  truly  vital 
interest  is  that  the  whole  class  should  rise  in  material  com- 
fort and  security,  and  still  more  in  moral  and  intellectual 
attainments."  2 

1  Inaugural  Address  delivered  at  the  Ipswich    Co-operative   Congress  (Man- 
chester, 1889),  p.  14. 

2  Work  and  the  Workman,  being  an  address  to  the  Trade   Union  Congress  at 
their  meeting  in  Dublin^  i6th  September  1880,  by  J.  K.  Ingram  (Dublin,  1880). 
It  must  not  be  inferred  that,  because  Trade  Unions  are  opposed  to  the  small 
master  system,  they   have  any  objection   to   their   members  rising   to   superior 
positions.      The  energetic  Trade  Unionist,  often  a  branch  official,  is  frequently 
selected  for  the  post  of  foreman,  which  he  accepts  with  the  full  approval  of  his 


,  we  find  a  l       "*         ^  the  Smali 

among  economists,  capitalists   InH       T"""0"3  ^eement 
d'fons  of  cmploymen  ^S'th"  sm"^        "'  that  the  co»- 
wage-earners  are  habitually  and  I  In  S°fH.masto  °«ers  to  his 
hose  of  the  great  establi  hment  "  1'  "'Iff1*'  Worse  'han 
health,    decency,    and    «SSSe    of  "  [  '^  C°"Cerns  the 
'"stance,  there  is  no  comparison   h  t  oP^atives,    for 

factory  and  the  CwJSSSnJt*"1  ^  m°der"  boot- 
"  of  the  small  maste  Nor  n,  T"  °f  "garden  work- 
quotations  to  prove  that  H?.  W6  Weary  the  Deader 
the  rates  of  payment  L^  h°Ur?f  'abor  ™  'onger 

'°         '" 


yment  r 

establishments  than  in  the  °It  c'"'^  ^"^  sl 
-Jch  they  compete.  The  vefy  advanf  enterPr-es  with 
•ndustry  on  a  ,  J^  advantages  which  are  causing 

system-the  utmost  S^*  the  «-"«   mastef 
division  of  labor,  the  obta  „" 
°"  the  cheapest  terms,  the  use 

e 


f  ,  °f 

of  th^i     l"^  raw 
the  °        ' 


_e       e   m  a 

e  for  existence,  to  be  perneT  "^  in  his  desperate 
lengthening  the  hour  of  labor  ^2  *<  *  l^"8  at  wa^  and 
^hom  he  employs.  It  s  a  'SIfrnfi  ?Se'f  Md  for  those 
master  system  is  found  to  be  a  fhl""*  faCt  that  *e  small 

as  Home  Work  itself  ^f^^.c  of  the  sweated 


^al  opportunity  of  5S7i        SyStem  of  the  Great  IndusT,^    rr       O"S'     To  the 


548  Trade  Union  Function 

were  proved  to  exist,  we  may  watch  the  poverty-stricken 
maker  of  tables  and  chairs  hawking  his  wares  along  Curtain 
Road,  selling  direct  to  the  export  merchant  or  to  the  retail 
tradesman,  or  perchance  to  the  private  customer.  In 
the  manufacture  of  cheap  boots  in  the  Metropolis,  of  cheap 
cutlery  at  Sheffield,  of  indifferent  nails  at  Halesowen,  we 
meet  with  this  same  sorrowful  figure — the  small  master  or 
outworker  buying  his  material  on  credit,  and  selling  his 
product  to  meet  the  necessities  of  the  hour ;  in  all  instances 
underselling  his  competitors  great  and  small.  Respectable 
employers,  interested  in  a  high  standard  of  production,  Trade 
Unionists  keen  for  a  high  standard  of  wage,  agree  in  attri- 
buting to  this  pitiful  personage  the  worst  evils  of  the  sweating 
system." 1 

If  then  the  Trade  Unionists  declare,  to  use  the  words  of 
a  Sheffield  secretary,  that  the  small  masters  "  are  a  curse  to 
the  trade  .  .  .  paying  starvation  wages  to  those  whom 
necessity  compels  to  work  for  them,"  this  is  not  due  to  any 
personal  dislike  of  the  small  masters,  or  to  any  aspersion  on 
their  character.  It  is  merely  the  recognition  by  Trade 
Unionists  of  an  economic  fact.  Thoughtful  workmen  in  the 
staple  trades  have  become  convinced,  by  their  own  experi- 
ence, no  less  than  by  the  repeated  arguments  of  the  econo- 
mists, that  a  rising  standard  of  wages  and  other  conditions 
of  employment  must  depend  ultimately  on  the  productivity 
of  labor,  and  therefore  upon  the  most  efficient  and  econo- 
mical use  of  credit,  capital,  and  capacity.  In  all  these 
respects  the  small  master  system  stands,  by  common  con- 
sent, condemned.  When,  therefore,  we  find  the  whole 
influence  of  Trade  Unionism  constantly  acting  against  this 
system,  and,  as  one  employer  na'rvely  put  it  to  us,  "  playing 
into  the  hands  of  the  great  establishments,"  we  must  at  any 
rate  credit  it  with  the  desire  so  far  to  promote  the  utmost 
possible  efficiency  of  production. 

This  scientific  argument  against  the  small  master  system 

1  "The  Lords  and  the  Sweating  System,"  by  Beatrice  Potter  (Mrs.  Sidney 
Webb),  Nineteenth  Century,  June  1890. 


-  -  - 

the 


«.  put  p»ctical,e  ^«  ty  enforcing  fc  Con,;." 
.yera.  Society  SJ  Srdl        '       '     Tte  °P™*« 


our  town 


;s« 


SE==S,ST. 

-= 


550  Trade  Union  Function 

work  done,  that  is  the  clearest  possible  proof  that  they  have 
no  right  to  exist  as  such.  There  is  no  animus  against  small 
manufacturers,  but  a  praiseworthy  determination  to  place  all, 
large  and  small,  upon  an  equal  wage  basis  ;  and  he  would 
be  a  bold  man  who  would  dare  to  find  fault  with  such  an 
arrangement."  *  It  is  exactly  at  this  "  equal  wage  basis  "  and 
similar  Common  Rules  throughout  the  whole  of  an  industry 
that  Trade  Unionism  persistently  aims.  The  ablest  leaders  of 
the  workmen's  combinations  are  therefore  instinctively  biassed 
in  favor  of  what  we  may  term  a  horizontal  cleavage  of 
industrial  classes,  and  they  are  necessarily  prejudiced  against 
any  interference  with  this  stratification.  They  are  conse- 
quently found  opposing  all  vertical  cleavages  whatever,  not 
merely  where,  as  in  the  cases  of  Home  Work  and  Small 
Masters,  these  involve  worse  conditions  for  the  wage-earners, 
but  also  in  the  less  noxious  forms  of  employers'  benefit 
societies  and  profit-sharing. 

At  first  sight  nothing  seems  more  kindly  and  humane 
on  the  part  of  the  employer,  and  less  open  to  objection  from 
the  workman's  standpoint,  than  the  establishment  of  a  Sick 
and  Burial  Club  in  connection  with  each  large  establishment. 
A  few  pence  per  week  are  stopped  from  the  operatives' 
earnings,  and  to  the  fund  thus  formed  the  employer  often 
adds  the  disciplinary  fines,  and  frequently  a  substantial  con- 
tribution from  the  firm,  in  whose  business  the  growing  capital 
is  invested.  To  the  middle-class  philanthropist  the  work- 
man's sullen  hostility  to  any  such  arrangement  appears 
"  ungrateful."  But  to  any  one  who  has  ever  understood  the 
assumptions  on  which  the  whole  Trade  Union  movement  is 
based,  the  wage-earner's  objection  will  be  clear  enough.  It 
is  not  merely  that  the  workmen  feel  no  guarantee  that,  in 
the  particular  financial  arrangements  imposed  on  them,  they 
are  getting  their  money's  worth ;  nor  is  the  objection  due 
to  any  doubt  as  to  the  security  of  the  fund — to  any  fear 
that,  just  when  they  need  their  sick  pay  or  superannuation, 
the  trade  may  be  depressed  and  the  firm  bankrupt.  What 

1  Editorial  in  Shoe  and  Leather  Record,  vol.  x.  p.  254,  loth  April  1891. 


Ttie  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism          55! 

the  Trade  Unionists  recognise  is  that  the  separate  interest 
thus  created  cuts  them  off  from  their  fellow-workmen  in 
other  establishments — that  a  vertical  cleavage  is  set  up  which 
interferes  with  Trade  Unionism.  We  have  seen  how  the 
fact  of  the  men  being  compelled  to  insure  against  sickness, 
cost  of  burial,  and  old  age  in  the  employer's  fund  renders 
them  indisposed  to  pay  over  again  to  the  Trade  Union.1 
But  there  is  a  more  fundamental  objection.  If,  as  is  usual, 
a  workman  forfeits  all  his  benefits  should  he  voluntarily 
leave  the  service  of  the  particular  firm,  there  is  a  strong  and 
growing  inducement  held  out  to  him  to  remain  where  he  is, 
and  thus  to  accept  the  employer's  terms.  He  loses,  in  fact, 
that  perfect  mobility  which,  as  economists  have  often  pointed 
out,  is  a  necessary  condition  of  his  making  the  best  possible 
bargain  for  the  sale  of  his  labor.  And,  to  the  Trade 
Unionist,  it  is  a  crowning  objection  that  the  workman  so 
tied  shuts  himself  out  from  all  the  advantages  of  concerted 
action  with  his  fellows.  Any  general  adoption  of  employers' 
benefit  societies  would,  in  fact,  go  far  to  render  Trade 
Unionism  impossible. 

Schemes  of  profit-sharing  are,  from  a  Trade  Union  point 
of  view,  open  to  similar  objections.  Unless  the  Standard 
Rate  and  other  conditions  are  rigidly  adhered  to,  the  work- 
men in  profit-sharing  establishments  may  easily  be  losing 
far  more  in  wages  than  they  gain  in  "  bonus  "  or  share  of 
profit.2  But  it  is  an  even  more  serious  objection  that  any 
separate  arrangements  with  particular  employers  destroy 
that  community  of  interest  throughout  the  trade  on  which 
Collective  Bargaining  depends.  The  men  employed  by  a 

1  It  was  stated  at  the  Annual  Conference  of  Friendly  Societies  in  March 
1897  that  particulars  had  been  obtained  of  forty  large  industrial  undertakings, 
including  the  Midland  Railway  Company,  in  which  insurance  in  the  employer's 
own  benefit  society  was  made  compulsory  on  all  persons  employed,  the  premium 
being  peremptorily  deducted  from  wages. 

2  Thus,  it  is  unusual  for  a  profit-sharing  establishment  to  afford  its  operatives 
a  larger  bonus  than   5  per  cent  on  their  wages,  and  few  do  even  as  well  as  this. 
But  except  in  the  most  rigidly  organised  trades,  in  the  strongest  Trade  Union 
districts,  it  is  common  to  find  some  employers  paying  several  shillings  per  week 
below  the  Standard  Rate  ;  still  more,  to  find  Piecework  Lists  in  different  establish- 
ments varying  from  10  to  20  per  cent. 


552  Trade  Union  Function 

specially  "  benevolent "  firm,  with  a  really  generous  profit- 
sharing  scheme,  will  not  be  disposed  to  join  heartily  with 
the  rest  in  any  movement  for  higher  wages,  lest  they  should 
lose  the  bonus  or  other  privileges  which  they  already  enjoy. 
Yet  whilst  they  stand  aloof,  contented  with  their  Standard 
Rate  of  wages  because  of  these  exceptional  privileges,  it  is 
difficult  for  the  workmen  elsewhere  to  make  any  effective 
stand  for  a  higher  rate.  To  the  Trade  Unionist  it  seems  a 
very  doubtful  kindness  for  an  employer  to  indulge  his  feelings 
of  philanthropy  in  such  a  way  as  to  weaken  the  capacity 
of  the  workmen  for  that  corporate  self-help  on  which  their 
defence  against  unscrupulous  employers  depends.  Looking 
at  the  matter  from  the  Trade  Union  standpoint,  an  employer 
who  desired  permanently  to  benefit  the  workmen  in  his 
trade  would  seek  in  every  way  to  promote  the  men's  own 
organisation,  and  would  therefore  make  his  own  establish- 
ment a  pattern  to  the  rest  in  respect  of  the  strictest  possible 
maintenance  of  the  Standard  Rates  of  wages,  hours  of  work, 
and  other  conditions  of  employment.  This  would  tend  to 
make  it  more  easy  for  the  workmen  in  other  establishments 
to  insist  on  the  same  advantages.  If  he  wished  to  do  more 
for  his  own  workmen,  and  could  afford  it,  he  would  scrupu- 
lously avoid  any  departure  from  the  standard  methods  of 
remuneration,  and  any  form  of  benevolence  which  created 
any  division  between  his  workmen  and  their  fellows.  What 
he  would  do  would  be  to  offer  a  simple  addition  to  the 
common  Standard  Rate,  or  a  simple  reduction  of  the  Normal 
Day  without  any  diminution  of  earnings.  In  this  way  any 
indirect  effect  upon  the  workmen  in  the  other  establishments 
would  be  in  the  direction  of  facilitating  their  claiming  similar 
advances. 

This  strong  objection  of  the  Trade  Unionists  to  any 
blurring  of  the  line  between  the  capitalist  profit-maker  and 
the  manual-working  wage-earner,  and  their  preference  for 
the  Great  Industry,  might,  at  first  sight,  seem  to  point  to- 
wards the  desirability  of  concentrating  each  trade  in  the 
hands  of  one  great  employer.  But  such  a  concentration  of 


The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism          553 

business  may,  from  the  Trade  Union  point  of  view,  easily 
be  carried  too  far.  When  in  any  trade  the  establishments 
are  all  sufficiently  large  to  make  it  easy  for  the  workmen  to 
combine,  the  Trade  Union  fights  at  the  greatest  strategic 
advantage  if  it  is  confronted  by  a  number  of  employers, 
varying  considerably  in  their  pecuniary  resources  and  oppor- 
tunities for  profit-making.  Thus,  in  any  coal,  engineering,  or 
cotton  strike,  the  circumstances  of  the  employers  differ  so 
greatly  that,  however  closely  they  may  be  combined,  there  is 
a  strong  tendency  for  some  of  them  to  split  off  from  the  rest. 
Those  making  exceptional  profits  will  not  care  obstinately 
to  stand  out  against  the  men's  demands,  and  so  lose  trade 
which  they  may  never  regain,  when  agreement  with  the 
Trade  Union  would  still  leave  them  a  handsome  surplus. 
To  firms  insufficiently  supplied  with  capital,  moreover,  a 
long  stoppage  may  easily  be  more  disastrous  than  anything 
that  the  Trade  Union  asks  for.  In  the  private  meetings  of 
any  employers'  association  during  a  strike,  these  two  classes 
are  always  pressing  for  a  settlement,  and  if  they  fail  to 
persuade  their  more  slow-going  and  highly-capitalised  com- 
petitors to  accept  their  view,  they  are  apt  at  last  to  make 
peace  on  their  own  account,  and  so  destroy  any  chance  of 
the  employers'  successful  resistance.1  If,  on  the  other  hand, 
the  whole  industry  is  controlled  by  a  single  colossal  em- 
ployer, or  if  it  is  distributed  among  a  small  number  of  non- 
competing  employers — especially  if  the  monopoly  is  in  any 
way  protected  against  new  rivals — the  Trade  Union  finds  its 
Methods  of  Mutual  Insurance  and  Collective  Bargaining 
practically  useless.  This  is  the  case  with  the  railway  com- 

1  "1  was  one  of  the  committee,"  observed  Mr.  Samuda,  the  great  London 
shipbuilder,  "for  carrying  on  that  contest  (the  engineers'  lock-out  of  1851),  and 
the  difficulties  that  existed  in  maintaining  a  combination  among  the  masters  were 
enormous,  because  there  were  so  many  masters  whose  necessities  were  so  great 
that  they  could  not  act  to  the  extent  of  resisting  demands  that  they  thought 
unjust.  It  was  only  men  who  were  thoroughly  independent,  and  who  did  not 
care  for  closing  their  works,  that  could  stand  the  difficulty,  and  face  the  insolvency 
that  was  brought  upon  weaker  houses  by  resisting  the  unjust  demands  of  the 
workmen." — Evidence  before  the  Royal  Commission  on  Trade  Unions,  1868, 
Q.  16,805. 


554  Trade  Union  Function 

panics  in  the  United  Kingdom,  and  some  of  the  great 
capitalist  trusts  in  the  United  States.  Against  the  unlimited 
resources,  the  secured  monopoly  of  custom,  and  the  absolute 
unity  of  will  enjoyed  by  these  modern  industrial  leviathans, 
the  quarter  of  a  million  accumulated  funds  of  the  richest 
Trade  Union,  and  the  clamor  of  even  one  or  two  hundred 
thousand  obstinate  and  embittered  workmen,  are  as  arrows 
against  ironclads.  In  such  cases  the  only  available  method 
of  securing  a  Common  Rule  is  Legal  Enactment — difficult, 
in  the  face  of  interests  so  powerful,  for  the  Trade  Unions  to 
obtain,  but  once  obtained,  in  so  highly  organised  an  industry, 
easy  of  application  and  enforcement.  We  may  therefore 
infer  that  the  extreme  concentration  of  industry  into  trusts 
and  monopolies  will  lead,  either  to  Trade  Union  failure  and 
decay,  or  else  to  an  almost  exclusive  reliance  on  the  Method 
of  Legal  Enactment. 

When  the  concentration  reaches  its  most  complete  form, 
and  industry  passes  into  State  Ownership,  the  Trade  Unions 
find  new  considerations  entering  into  their  problems. 
When  the  employer  is  the  State  itself,  the  strongest  and 
richest  Trade  Union  is  as  powerless  to  stand  out  for  terms 
as  the  individual  workman.  A  long  strike  will  bankrupt 
dozens  of  employers  and  seriously  reduce  the  dividends  of 
even  the  wealthiest  trust.  But  if  all  the  workmen  in  the 
Admiralty  dockyards  stayed  out  for  a  year,  neither  the  Civil 
Servant  manager  nor  the  citizen  proprietor  would  find  his 
daily  income  even  fractionally  diminished.  The  Trade 
Unions  are  so  conscious  of  this  economic  helplessness  that 
they  never  order  a  strike  in  a  Government  establishment, 
and  they  scarcely,  indeed,  attempt  to  bargain  with  so  over- 
whelming an  omnipotence.  Wherever  the  State  is  dominated 
by  classes  or  interests  who  do  not  share  the  Trade  Union 
faith,  the  Trade  Unionists,  as  such,  will  therefore  be  dead 
against  the  extension  of  State  Socialism  in  their  own  particular 
industries.1  The  case  is  altered  if  the  conditions  of  Govern- 

1  Thus  the  German  delegates  to  the  International  Miners' Congress  of  1897 
iheld  in  London)  objected  to  the  resolution  in  favor  of  the  "  nationalisation  of  the 


The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism          555 

ment  employment  can  be  influenced  by  democratic  public 
opinion.  If  Parliament  were  really  prepared  to  insist  on  the 
conditions  of  Government  employment  being  brought  into 
conformity  with  Trade  Union  regulations,  any  extension  of 
the  public  administration  of  industry  might  well  secure  Trade 
Union  support.  At  present,  however,  the  Trade  Union  in- 
fluence on  the  conditions  of  Government  employment  is,  in 
spite  of  appearances,  extremely  ineffective.  The  Trade  Union 
world,  with  the  exception  of  the  Cotton  Operatives  and 
Coalminers,  is,  as  we  have  pointed  out,  unable  to  make  its 
political  power  felt  in  Parliament.  Nor  is  the  House  of 
Commons,  as  at  present  organised,  competent,  even  if  it 
were  really  willing,  effectively  to  supervise  the  internal 
administration  of  the  great  public  departments.  Finally, 
we  have  the  fact  that  the  present  generation  of  the  higher 
Civil  Servants — our  real  rulers  in  points  of  administrative 
detail — are,  for  the  most  part,  invincibly  ignorant  both  of 
industrial  organisation  and  modern  economics,  and  are 
usually  imbued  with  the  crudest  prejudices  of  the  Manchester 
School.  It  is  in  vain  that  Ministry  after  Ministry  avows  its 
intention  of  abandoning  competition  wages,  and  of  making 
the  Government  a  "  model  employer."  The  permanent 
heads  of  departments  have  no  intention  of  departing  from 
the  "  sound  "  principles  which  they  brought  into  the  service 
in  1 860  or  1870.  Hence,  a  Trade  Union  secretary  will  often 
declare  that  the  Government,  instead  of  being  the  best,  is  one 
of  the  very  worst  employers  with  whom  he  has  to  deal. 

But  even   in  the  most  complete  and  the  most  perfectly 
organised  Democracy,  there  would  be  influences  which  would 

mines,"  on  the  express  ground  that  "  they  in  Germany  had  found  that  the  capitalistic 
State  was  the  worst  possible  employer,  and  the  worst  enemy  and  opponent  of 
the  workers.  There  happened  to  be  in  Germany  some  very  large  State  mines, 
and  the  conditions  of  the  workers  in  these  mines  was  infinitely  worse  than  else- 
where. Now  the  State  was  indifferent  during  mining  disputes.  If  it  possessed 
all  the  mines,  it  would  be  as  an  employer  more  powerful  and  more  tyrannical 
than  a  private  employer"  (Daily  Chronicle,  1 2th  June  1897).  It  is  interesting 
to  note  that  the  French  and  Belgian  delegates  unanimously  supported  the 
resolution,  together  with  a  majority  of  the  English  (those  from  Northumberland 
and  Durham  alone  dissenting),  whilst  the  Germans,  though  mostly  members  of 
the  Social  Democratic  Party,  abstained. 


556  Trade  Union  Function 

prevent  the  Government,  as  an  employer,  giving  universal  satis- 
faction to  the  Trade  Unions.  Though  the  working-class  vote 
would  be  overwhelming,  each  section  of  wage-earners  would 
find  itself  a  small  minority  among  the  rest,  and  would  dis- 
cover accordingly  how  difficult  it  was  to  force  its  own 
peculiar  grievances  upon  public  attention.  And,  though  any 
section  that  was  "  underpaid  "  or  "  overworked  "  would  get 
sympathetic  support,  there  would  be  a  strong  tendency  in 
the  average  man  to  object  to  any  terms  that  were  out  of  the 
common.  Sections  of  workmen  who  had,  under  private 
enterprise,  been  enjoying  exceptionally  high  wages  or  short 
hours,  or  who  had  been  enforcing  strict  limitation  of 
numbers  or  other  monopoly  conditions,  would  find  it  difficult 
to  maintain  these  by  appeals  to  the  multitude.  The  men  in 
these  trades  would  accordingly,  as  Trade  Unionists,  tend 
always  to  be  discontented  with  Government  employment. 
Thus,  public  administration  of  industry  under  Democratic 
control  will  be  most  popular  among  those  larger  sections  of 
the  wage-earners,  who  at  present  suffer  from  the  weakness  of 
their  strategic  position,  and  will  remain  unpopular  among 
the  smaller  and  better  organised  sections,  who  can  now  take 
advantage  of  their  corporate  strength  to  exact  from  their 
private  employers  monopoly  terms. 

These  considerations  apply  with  less  force  to  municipal 
employment.  The  Town  Council,  though  more  powerful 
in  Collective  Bargaining  than  any  private  employer,  has 
nothing  like  the  omnipotence  of  the  great  State  Department. 
A  strike  at  the  municipal  gas  retorts,  or  in  the  workshops  of 
the  Borough  Engineer,  is  a  serious  matter,  which  must  be 
quickly  brought  to  an  end,  under  penalty  of  the  immediate 
displeasure  of  the  citizen-consumers.  And  whilst  the  Town 
Council  is  weaker  than  Parliament  in  strategic  position,  it  is 
also  more  amenable  to  public  opinion.  Municipal  electoral 
machinery  has  been  more  thoroughly  democratised  than 
parliamentary,  and  is  therefore  easier  of  access  to  the  local 
unions.  No  great  issues  of  foreign  policy,  religion,  currency, 
or  constitutional  reform  divide  the  workmen's  ranks.  The 


The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism          557 

moral  effect  of  the  Town  Council's  policy  with  regard  to  the 
conditions  of  employment  is  understood  by  every  Trade 
Unionist.  Once  the  Town  Councillors  are  converted,  the  per- 
manent officials  have  no  chance  of  evading  or  obstructing  the 
decision  of  the  local  Representative  Assembly.  Moreover, 
the  lowlier  grades  of  manual  labor  contribute  a  larger  pro- 
portion of  the  municipal  than  they  do  of  the  national 
employees.1  There  is  as  yet  nothing  in  the  municipal 
service  comparable  to  the  great  establishments  of  highly 
skilled  shipwrights  and  engineers  of  the  national  dock- 
yards and  arsenals.  It  is,  as  we  have  suggested,  far  more 
easy  for  the  Trade  Unions  to  obtain  electoral  support 
for  a  universal  "  moral  minimum,"  or  "  fair  wages,"  based  on 
the  cost  of  subsistence,  than  for  any  superior  conditions, 
established  by  trade  custom  or  gained  by  strategic  advantage, 
in  respect  of  particular  sections  of  workmen.  We  therefore 
find  the  skilled  trades  less  hostile,  as  Trade  Unionists,  to  the 
municipal  administration  of  industry  than  to  any  extension 
of  State  employment,  whilst  the  "  sweated  trades  "  and  the 
unskilled  laborers  clamor  for  the  abolition  of  the  con- 
tractor, and  the  direct  employment  of  labor,  as  their  main 
hope  of  salvation. 

If,  now,  we  look  back  on  the  incidental  features  of  Trade 
Union  policy  described  in  this  chapter,  we  may  gain  some 
insight  into  the  kind  of  social  arrangements  to  which 
Trade  Unionism  predisposes  the  British  workman  of  our 
own  day. 

Most  fundamental  of  all  considerations  to  the  Trade 
Unionist  is  complete  freedom  of  association.  This  means, 
that  whilst  the  law  must  afford  full  protection  to  the  funds 
of  workmen's  associations,  it  should  leave  them  as  much 
as  possible  alone ;  and  that  it  should,  in  particular,  regard 
nothing  as  criminal  or  actionable  if  done  by  or  in  pursuance 

1  Thus,  in  London  in  1891,  even  after  a  general  improvement  of  conditions, 
Mr.  Charles  Booth  found  that  the  great  class  of  "  Municipal  Labor  "  came 
within  six  of  the  worst  of  his  eighty-seven  occupations,  in  the  percentage  of  families 
living  in  an  overcrowded  condition. — Life  and  Labour  of  the  People^  vol.  ix.  p.  8- 


558  Trade  Union  Function 

of  a  combination  of  workmen  which  would  not  be  criminal 
or  actionable  if  done  by  a  partnership  of  traders  in  pursuit 
of  their  own  gain.  But  whilst  the  Trade  Unionists  insist  on 
their  combinations  being  let  alone  by  the  law,  they  wish  to 
use  the  law  to  attain  their  own  particular  end — the  systematic 
regulation  of  the  conditions  of  employment  by  means  of  the 
Common  Rule.  Hence  their  desire  for  a  completely  demo- 
cratised electoral  system,  in  which  the  will  of  the  majority 
shall  really  prevail.  With  regard  to  the  organisation  of 
industry,  we  see  the  Trade  Unions  setting  themselves 
decidedly  against  any  vertical  cleavage  of  society,  which 
interferes  with  the  solidarity  of  the  manual-working  wage- 
earners  as  against  the  capitalist  employers.  This  means 
that  Trade  Unionists,  as  such,  are  not  in  favor  of  the 
"  abolition  of  the  wage  system,"  or  even  of  any  tampering 
with  it.  They  would,  on  the  contrary,  wish  to  see  simple 
employment  at  wages  supersede  all  forms  of  profit-making 
by  manual  workers.  They  are  thus  solidly  against  Home 
Work,  Small  Masters,  and  Profit-Sharing,  and  in  favor  of 
the  Great  Industry,  with  its  bureaucratic  hierarchy  of  salaried 
officials.  When,  however,  the  Great  Industry  passes  into 
public  administration,  Trade  Unionists,  as  such,  regard  the 
change  with  mixed  feelings.  Government  Employment  goes 
far  to  make  two  out  of  their  three  Methods  impracticable, 
and  they  have  as  yet  no  confidence  in  the  will  and  capacity 
of  the  House  of  Commons  to  overcome  the  hostility  to 
labor  of  the  permanent  Civil  Service.  With  local  authorities 
the  Trade  Unions  have  a  better  chance,  but  even  here,  though 
the  underpaid  and  overworked  sections  welcome  municipal 
employment,  the  most  highly  paid  unions  hesitate  to  invite 
the  verdict  of  public  opinion  on  their  restrictive  regulations 
and  monopoly  conditions. 


CHAPTER    XIII 

THE    ASSUMPTIONS    OF    TRADE    UNIONISM 

So  far  we  have  confined  ourselves  to  setting  forth  and 
explaining  the  actual  policy  of  British  Trade  Unionism,  as 
manifested  in  the  Methods  and  Regulations  of  the  several 
Unions,  and  their  direct  implications.  We  have  still  to 
examine  these  Methods  and  Regulations,  together  with  the 
policy  of  Trade  Unionism  as  a  whole,  in  the  light  of 
economic  science,  and  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  com- 
munity. But  before  we  pass  to  this  new  task  it  is  important 
to  drag  into  full  light  the  assumptions  on  which  the  Trade 
Unionists  habitually  base  both  their  belief  in  Trade  Union- 
ism itself  and  their  justification  of  particular  demands. 
These  assumptions,  seldom  explicitly  set  forth,  will  serve  at 
once  to  explain,  and  in  a  sense  to  summarise,  the  Methods 
and  Regulations  which  they  inspire. 

We  have  first  the  typical  assumption  of  all  reformers  in 
all  ages — the  conviction  that  economic  and  social  conditions 
can,  by  deliberate  human  intervention,  be  changed  for  the 
better.1  Trade  Unionists  have  never  even  understood  the 

1  This  belief  in  the  possibility  and  desirability  of  deliberately  altering  the 
conditions  of  social  life  is  often  regarded  as  unscientific,  if  not  as  impious.  Any 
intentional  change  is  denounced  as  "  artificial " — it  being  apparently  supposed 
that  changes  unintentionally  produced  are  more  "natural"  than  others,  and  more 
likely  to  result  in  the  ends  we  desire.  Even  Mr.  Lecky  makes  it  a  matter  of 
reproach  to  Trade  Unionism,  modern  Radicalism,  and  other  movements  which 
he  dislikes,  that  their  policy  is  "to  create  a  social  type  different  from  that  which 
the  unrestricted  play  of  social  forces  would  have  produced  " — a  policy  which  he 
declares  "belongs  to  the  same  order  of  ideas  as  the  Protectionism  of  the  past" 


560  J^rade  Union  Function          _m 

view — still  occasionally  met  with — that  there  is  an  abso- 
lutely predetermined  "  Wage-Fund,"  and  that  the  average 
workman's  share  of  the  produce  depends  exclusively  on  the 
arithmetical  proportion  between  the  total  of  this  fund  and 
the  number  of  wage-earners.  They  assume,  on  the  contrary, 
that  the  ratio  in  which  the  total  product  of  industry  is  shared 
between  the  property-owners,  the  brain-workers,  and  the 
manual  laboring  class  respectively,  is  a  matter  of  human 
arrangement,  and  that  it  can  be  altered,  effectively  and  per- 
manently, to  the  advantage  of  one  class  or  another,  if  the 
appropriate  action  be  taken.  This  assumption  we  shall 
examine  in  detail  in  the  next  chapter. 

For  the  improvement  of  the  conditions  of  employment, 
whether  in  respect  of  wages,  hours,  health,  safety,  or  comfort, 
the  Trade  Unionists  have,  with  all  their  multiplicity  of  Regu- 
lations, really  only  two  expedients,  which  we  term,  respect- 
ively, the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule,  and  the  Device  of 
Restriction  of  Numbers.  The  Regulations  which  we  have 
described  in  our  chapters  on  the  Standard  Rate,  the  Normal 
Day,  and  Sanitation  and  Safety,  are  but  different  forms  of  one 
principle — the  settlement,  whether  by  Mutual  Insurance, 
Collective  Bargaining,  or  Legal  Enactment,  of  minimum  con- 
ditions of  employment,  by  Common  Rules  applicable  to 
whole  bodies  of  workers.  All  these  Regulations  are  based 
on  the  assumption  that  when,  in  the  absence  of  any  Com- 
mon Rule,  the  conditions  of  employment  are  left  to  "  free 
competition,"  this  always  means,  in  practice,  that  they  are 
arrived  at  by  Individual  Bargaining  between  contracting 
parties  of  very  unequal  economic  strength.  Such  a  settle- 
ment, it  is  asserted,  invariably  tends,  for  the  mass  of  the 

(Democracy  and  Liberty,  vol.  ii.  p.  383).  To  any  scientific  student  of  sociology 
such  language  is  unintelligible.  "To  create  a  social  type  different  from  that 
which  the  free  play  of  social  forces  would  have  produced  "  without  such  "  artificial 
intervention  "  is  a  policy  which  Trade  Unionism  shares,  not  only  with  fiscal  pro- 
tection, but  with  all  education  and  invention,  the  Church  of  England  and  the  Courts 
of  Justice,  private  property  and  the  family,  and  all  other  social  institutions,  good, 
bad,  or  indifferent.  Civilisation  itself  is  nothing  but  the  creation  of  a  social  type 
different  from  that  which  the  unrestricted  play  of  social  forces  would  have  pro- 
duced without  the  deliberate,  or  "artificial,"  intervention  of  man. 


T lie  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          561 

workers,  towards  the  worst  possible  conditions  of  labor — 
ultimately,  indeed,  to  the  barest  subsistence  level — whilst 
even  the  exceptional  few  do  not  permanently  gain  as  much 
as  they  otherwise  could.  We  find  accordingly  that  the 
Device  of  the  Common  Rule  is  a  universal  feature  of  Trade 
Unionism,  and  that  the  assumption  on  which  it  is  based 
is  held  from  one  end  of  the  Trade  Union  world  to  the 
other.  The  Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers  stands  in  a 
different  position.  In  our  chapter  on  the  Entrance  to  a 
Trade  we  have  described  how  the  Regulations  embodying 
this  device,  once  adopted  as  a  matter  of  course,  have  suc- 
cessively been  found  inapplicable  to  the  circumstances  of 
modern  industry.  The  assumption  on  which  they  are  based 
— that  better  conditions  can  be  obtained  by  limiting  the 
number  of  competitors — would  not  be  denied  by  any  Trade 
Unionist,  but  it  cannot  be  said  to  form  an  important  part  in 
the  working  creed  of  the  Trade  Union  world.  In  summing 
up  the  economic  results  of  Trade  Unionism  it  is  on  these 
two  Devices  of  the  Common  Rule  and  Restriction  of 
Numbers  that  we  shall  concentrate  our  criticism. 

But  these  initial  assumptions  as  to  the  need  for  Trade 
Unionism  and  the  efficacy  of  its  two  devices  do  not,  of  them- 
selves, account  for  the  marked  divergence  between  different 
Unions,  alike  in  the  general  character  of  their  policy  and  in 
the  Regulations  which  they  enforce.  The  universal  belief  in 
a  Common  Rule  affords,  to  begin  with,  no  guidance  as  to 
how  much  wages  the  members  of  a  particular  trade  will 
claim  or  receive,  or  how  many  hours  they  will  consider  to  be 
a  proper  working  day.  There  is,  in  fact,  no  "  Trade  Union 
Rate  of  Wages,"  but  many  different  rates — not  even  a 
"  Trade  Union  Working  Day,"  but  hours  of  labor  varying 
from  occupation  to  occupation.  This  divergence  of  policy 
comes  out  even  more  strikingly  in  the  adoption  or  rejection 
of  the  Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers,  a  few  trades  still 
making  the  strict  Limitation  of  Apprentices  and  the  Exclu- 
sion of  Illegal  Men  a  leading  feature  of  their  policy,  whilst 
others  throw  their  trades  absolutely  open  to  all  comers,  and 
VOL.  II  20 


562  Trade  Union  Function 

rely  exclusively  on  the  maintenance  of  the  Common  Rule. 
This  divergence  of  policy  and  difference  in  type  between  one 
Trade  Union  and  another  comes  out  strongly  in  the  choice  of 
the  Methods  by  which  they  enforce  their  Regulations.  The 
Boilermakers,  for  instance,  rely  very  largely  on  Collective 
Bargaining,  whilst  the  Coalminers  get  at  least  as  much  by 
Legal  Enactment  as  by  any  other  Method.  During  the 
eighteenth  century  any  trade  wishing  to  enforce  apprentice- 
ship regulations  turned,  as  a  matter  of  course,  to  the  law. 
To-day  no  union  would  resort  to  Parliament  on  such  a 
point.  A  hundred  and  fifty  years  ago  it  was  especially  the 
skilled  craftsmen  who  wanted  their  wages  fixed  by  Legal 
Enactment.  At  present  such  favor  as  is  shown  to  this  idea 
comes  almost  exclusively  from  the  lowlier  grades  of  labor. 
On  all  these  points  the  action  of  any  particular  union — the 
way  in  which  it  will  seek  to  use  the  Device  of  the  Common 
Rule — is  mainly  determined  by  the  views  of  its  members  as 
to  what  is  socially  expedient.  In  the  wider  world  of  politics 
we  see  the  electors  supporting  the  policy  of  one  or  other 
political  party  mainly  according  as  they  approve  or  dis- 
approve of  the  general  conception  of  society  on  which  it  pro- 
ceeds. The  Trade  Unionists,  in  their  narrower  sphere  of  the 
conditions  of  employment,  are  influenced  by  three  divergent 
conceptions  of  the  principle  upon  which  wages,  hours,  and 
other  terms  of  the  labor  contract  ought  to  be  determined. 
These  three  assumptions,  which  we  distinguish  as  the 
Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests,  the  Doctrine  of  Supply  and 
Demand,  and  the  Doctrine  of  a  Living  Wage,  give  us  the 
clue  to  the  conflicting  policies  of  the  Trade  Union  world. 

By  the  Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests  we  mean  the 
assumption  that  the  wages  and  other  conditions  of  employ- 
ment hitherto  enjoyed  by  any  section  of  workmen  ought 
under  no  circumstances  to  be  interfered  with  for  the  worse. 
It  was  this  doctrine,  as  we  have  seen,  which  inspired  the  long 
struggle,  lasting  down  to  about  1860,  against  the  introduction 
of  machinery,  or  any  innovation  in  processes.  It  is  this 
doctrine  which  to-day  gives  the  bitterness  to  demarcation 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          563 

disputes,  and  lies  at  the  back  of  all  the  Regulations  dealing 
with  the  "  right  to  a  trade." *  It  does  more  than  anything 
else  to  keep  alive  the  idea  of  "  patrimony  "  and  the  practice 
of  a  lengthened  period  of  apprenticeship,  whilst  it  induces 
the  workmen  of  particular  trades  to  cling  fondly  to  the  ex- 
pedient of  limiting  the  numbers  entering  those  trades,  even 
after  experience  has  proved  such  a  limitation  to  be  imprac- 
ticable. But  the  Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests  extends  much 
further  than  these  particular  Regulations.  There  is  scarcely 
an  industry  in  which  it  will  not  be  found,  on  one  occasion  or 
another,  inspiring  the  defence  of  the  customary  rates  of  wages 
or  any  threatened  privilege.  In  some  cases,  indeed,  we  find 
the  whole  argument  for  Trade  Unionism  based  on  this  one 
conception.  The  Engineers,  for  instance,  in  1845  supported 
their  case  by  a  forcible  analogy.  "  The  youth  who  has 
the  good  fortune  and  inclinations  for  preparing  himself 
as  a  useful  member  of  society  by  the  study  of  physic,  and 
who  studies  that  profession  with  success  so  as  to  obtain 
his  diploma  from  the  Surgeons'  Hall,  or  the  College  of 
Surgeons,  naturally  expects  in  some  measure  that  he  is 
entitled  to  privileges  to  which  the  pretending  quack  can 
lay  no  claim  ;  and  if  in  the  practice  of  that  useful  profes- 
sion he  finds  himself  injured  by  such  a  pretender,  he  has  the 
power  of  instituting  a  course  of  law  against  him.  Such  are 
the  benefits  connected  with  the  learned  professions.  But  the 
mechanic,  though  he  may  expend  nearly  an  equal  fortune, 
and  sacrifice  an  equal  portion  of  his  life,  in  becoming  ac- 
quainted with  the  different  branches  of  useful  mechanism,  has 
no  law  to  protect  his  privileges.  It  behoves  him,  therefore, 

1  We  see  this,  for  instance,  among  the  Engineers.  "  The  question  as  to  a 
turner  working  the  horizontal  boring  lathe  at  the  Pallion  [Works]  .  .  .  remains 
unsettled  ;  the  employers  adhering  to  their  right  of  '  selecting  the  men  and 
apportioning  the  work.'  The  issue  appears  to  be  clean  cut,  and  stated  with 
perfect  frankness.  The  vested  interest — equally  with  employers — of  workmen  in 
a  trade  by  probationary  servitude  is  apparently  to  be  set  at  naught.  To  displace 
a  journeyman,  as  indicated,  in  the  exercise  of  the  'right  of  selecting,'  in  the 
manner  proposed,  is  as  much  a  wrong  as  if  the  same  process  was  proposed  to  be 
adopted  with  respect  to  the  employer's  capital." — Report  of  Tyneside  District 
Delegate,  in  Amalgamated  Engineers'  Monthly  Journal,  May  1897. 


564  Trade  Union  Function 

on  all  reasonable  grounds,  and  by  all  possible  means,  to 
secure  the  advantages  of  a  society  like  this  to  himself."  1  The 
same  idea  is  put  with  no  less  clearness  by  some  of  the  smaller 
trades.  "  Considering,"  say  the  Birmingham  Wireworkers, 
"  that  the  trade  by  which  we  live  is  our  property,  bought  by 
certain  years  of  servitude,  which  gives  to  us  a  vested  right, 
and  that  we  have  a  sole  and  exclusive  claim  on  it,  as  all  will 
have  hereafter  who  purchase  it  by  the  same  means.  Such 
being  the  case,  it  is  evident  it  is  our  duty  to  protect,  by  all 
fair  and  legal  means,  the  property  by  which  we  live,  being 
always  equally  careful  not  to  trespass  on  the  rights  of  others. 
To  that  end  we  have  formed  this  Association,"  etc.2 

This  conception  of  vested  interests  is  sometimes  carried 
as  far  by  working  men  as  by  the  powerful  organisation  which 
has  latterly  become  distinctively  known  as  "  The  Trade." 
Thus  the  Coopers,  whose  chief  employers  then  as  now  were 
the  brewers,  were  in  1883  keenly  resenting  the  spread  of 
education  and  temperance,  and  the  threatened  measure  of 
"  Local  Option."  "  Several  Yorkshire  towns,"  remarked  their 
official  circular,  "have  for  years  until  recently  been  great 
centres  of  industry  in  the  export  line.  These  centres  of 
industry  are  swept  away,  and  nothing  I  am  sorry  to  say 
has  turned  up  to  replace  them,  the  consequence  being  that 
all  these  men  had  to  obtain  blocks  elsewhere.  There  is  also 
the  spread  of  education,  an  all-powerful  influence  we  are 
bound  to  feel,  and  a  blow  from  which  we  shall  not  easily 
recover.  There  is  also  that  great  Northern  baronet,  Sir 
Wilfrid,  he  too,  like  Demetrius  the  Silversmith  of  Macedonia, 
and  Alexander  the  Athenian  Coppersmith,  has  wrought  us 

1  Rides  and  Regulations  to  be  observed  by  the  Members  of  the  Journeymen 
Steam  Engine  and  Machine  Makers'  and  Millwrights*  Friendly  Society  (Glasgow, 
1845).     This  analogy  is  repeated  in  substance  in  many  editions  of  the  rules  of 
the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers. 

2  Extract  from  Address,  prefaced  to  the  Rules  and  Regulations  of  the  Birming- 
ham Friendly  Society  of  Wire  Weavers,  a  small  union  instituted  August   1869. 
The  same  preamble  was  used  by  the  Railway  Springmakers  of  Sheffield  in  the 
Rules  of  their  Society  in   1860;  see  "Report  on  Trade  Societies'  Rules"  in  the 
Report  on  Trade  Societies  and  Strikes  of  the  National  Association  for  the  Pro- 
motion of  Social  Science  (London,  1860),  pp.  131-132. 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          565 

much  evil,  and  from  the  tone  of  his  speeches  means  to  continue 
to  dp  so." 1 

It  is  difficult  for  middle-class  observers,  accustomed  to 
confine  the  doctrine  of  "  vested  interests "  to  "  rights  of 
property,"  to  understand  the  fervor  and  conviction  with 
which  the  skilled  artisan  holds  this  doctrine  in  its  application 
to  the  "  right  to  a  trade."  This  intuitive  conviction  of  natural 
right  we  ascribe,  in  great  part,  to  the  long  and  respectable 
history  of  the  idea.  Down  to  the  middle  of  the  eighteenth 
century  it  was  undisputed.  To  the  member  of  a  Craft  Gild 
or  Incorporated  Company  it  seemed  as  outrageous,  and  as 
contrary  to  natural  justice,  for  an  unlicensed  interloper  to 
take  his  trade  as  for  a  thief  to  steal  his  wares.  Nor  was 
this  conception  confined  to  any  particular  section  of  the 
community.  To  the  economists  and  statesmen  of  the  time 
the  protection  of  the  vested  interests  of  each  class  of  trades- 
men appeared  a  no  less  fundamental  axiom  of  civilised 
society  than  the  protection  of  property  in  land  or  chattels. 
"Our  forefathers,"  said  the  Emperor  Sigismund  in  1434, 
"  have  not  been  fools.  The  crafts  have  been  devised  for  this 
purpose  that  everybody  by  them  should  earn  his  daily  bread, 
and  nobody  shall  interfere  with  the  craft  of  another.  By 
this  the  world  gets  rid  of  its  misery,  and  every  one  may  find 
his  livelihood."2  "The  first  rule  of  justice,"  said  the  Parlia- 
ment of  Paris  three  hundred  and  fifty  years  later,  "is  to 
preserve  to  every  one  what  belongs  to  him  ;  this  rule  consists, 

1  Monthly  Report  of  the  Mutual  Association  of  Coopers,  Feb.  1883.     This 
conception  of  a  "vested  interest  "  in  the  nation's  drinking  habits  may  be  paralleled 
by  the  attempts  made  to  give  the  "sanctity  of  property"  to  the  employer's  power 
of  hiring   his  labor  cheap,   or  working  it  excessive  hours.       Thus  Sir  James 
Graham,  speaking  in  the  House  of  Commons  as  a  responsible  minister  of  the 
Crown,    solemnly   denounced   the    Ten    Hours'  Bill   of   1844  as    "Jack   Cade 
Legislation"  (Greville's  Journal  of  the  Reign  of  Queen  Victoria,  vol.  ii.  p.  236  ; 
see  The  Eight  Hours'  Day  by  Sidney  Webb  and  Harold  Cox,   London,  1891, 
p.  240),  and   a  leading  Lancashire  manufacturer  in   1860  publicly  argued  that 
"the  power  of  the  Trade  Union  .   .  .   robs  (for  I  can  use  no  milder  term)  .   .   . 
the  capitalist  of  his  right  to  purchase." — "  Trades  Unions  and  their  Tendencies," 
by  Edmund  Potter,  a  paper  printed  in  the  Transactions  of  the  National  Association 
for  the  Promotion  of  Social  Science,  1860,  p.  758. 

2  Goldasti's  Constitutions  Imperiales,  vol.  iv.  p.  189,  quoted  by  Dr.  Brentano, 
p.  60  ;  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  p.  19. 


566  Trade  Union  Function 

not  only  in  preserving  the  rights  of  property,  but  still  more 
in  preserving  those  belonging  to  the  person,  which  arise  from 
the  prerogative  of  birth  and  of  position."  l  "  To  give  to  all 
subjects  indiscriminately,"  argued  on  that  occasion  the 
eminent  Advocate -General  Se"guier,  "the  right  to  hold  a 
store  or  to  open  a  shop  is  to  violate  the  property  of  those 
who  form  the  incorporated  crafts."2 

But  this  conception  of  a  vested  interest  in  a  trade,  though 
it  derives  sanction  among  an  essentially  conservative  class 
from  its  long  and  venerable  history,  does  not  rest  upon 
tradition  alone.  To  men  dependent  for  daily  existence  on 
continuous  employment,  the  protection  of  their  means  of 
livelihood  from  confiscation  or  encroachment  appears  as 
fundamental  a  basis  of  social  order  as  it  does  to  the  owners 
of  land.  What  both  parties  claim  is  security  and  continuity 
of  livelihood — that  maintenance  of  the  "  established  expecta- 
tion" which  is  the  "condition  precedent"  of  civilised  life.  And 
it  is  easy  to  trace  this  social  expediency  to  an  elementary 
observation  on  personal  character.  When  misfortune  arrives 
in  consequence  of  a  man's  own  act  or  default,  it  may  well 
bring  the  compensation  of  inducing  him  to  change  his  habits. 
But  when  individuals  or  classes  are  overwhelmed  by  disasters 
which  they  could  have  done  nothing  to  avert,  experience 
shows  that,  though  they  may  be  led  to  passive  resignation, 
they  are  not  stimulated  to  self-reliance,  and  they  are  apt,  on 
the  contrary,  to  be  rendered  inert  or  reckless.  We  do  not 
expect  deliberate  foresight  or  persistent  industry  from  a 
community  living  on  a  volcano.3  This,  indeed,  is  the 

1  Remonstrance  by  the  Parliament  of  Paris  against  Turgot's  Decrees  abolishing 
the  Corvee  and  the  Jurandes ;    Life  and  Writings  of  Turgot,  by  W.  Walker 
Stephens,  p.  132  ;  Jobez,  La  France  sous  Louis  XVI.  i.  329-331. 

2  Speech  of  the  Advocate  Seguier  on  behalf  of  the  Jurandes  at  the  Lit  de 
Justice  for  registering  Turgot's  Decree  ;  Life  and  Writings  of  Turgot,  by  W. 
Walker  Stephens,  p.  134  ;   QLnvrcs  de  Turgot,  ii.  334-337  ;  Foncin,  liv.  iii.  c.  ix. 

3  Buckle  notices  the  effect  of  earthquakes  in  weakening  character;    "men 
witnessing  the  most  serious  dangers  which  they  can  neither  avoid  nor  understand, 
become  impressed  with  a  conviction  of  their  inability,  and  of  the  poverty  of  their 
own  resources  "  (History  of  Civilisation,  vol.  i.  p.  123).     Middle-class  critics  often 
deplore  the  "  heedlessness  "  as  to  the  future — the  lack  of  persistent  carrying  out 
of  a  deliberate  plan  of  life — which  marks  the  laborer  engaged  in  a  fluctuating 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          567 

fundamental  argument  against  anything  which  weakens  the 
feeling  of  security  of  private  property,  that  is,  against  any 
"  shock  or  derangement  being  given  to  the  expectation  which 
has  been  founded  on  the  laws  of  enjoying  a  certain  portion 
of  good."  1  And  if  we  pass  from  the  ownership  of  property 
to  its  occupation  under  contract,  we  shall  recognise  the  same 
argument  in  the  agitation  long  and  successfully  carried  on 
by  Irish  and  English  farmers  for  a  law  which  should  secure 
them  in  their  "  tenant  right."  It  has  now  been  conceded 
that  we  cannot  expect  occupiers  of  land  to  exercise  the 
self-sacrifice,  foresight,  and  energy  necessary  to  keep  their 
holdings  in  the  highest  possible  efficiency,  if  the  results  of 
their  work  can  be  arbitrarily  confiscated  whenever  a  landlord 
chooses  to  exercise  his  legal  right  of  ejecting  a  tenant.  A 
similar  consideration  lies  at  the  base  of  the  universal  conviction 
in  favor  of  a  legally  regulated  currency.  Bimetallists  and 
monometallists  alike  deplore  the  disastrous  effect  on  national 
enterprise  if,  in  the  absence  of  a  deliberately  settled  standard 
of  value,  the  reasonable  expectations  of  merchants  and 
manufacturers  are  set  at  naught  by  currency  fluctuations 
over  which  they  can  have  no  control.  We  need  not  weary 
the  reader  by  citing  other  instances  (such  as  the  law  of 
patents  and  copyright,  the  universal  practice  of  compensation 
for  abolition  of  office,  and  all  the  thousand  and  one  claims 
of  persons  "injuriously  affected,"  which  are  sanctioned  by 
the  English  Lands  Clauses  Consolidation  Acts),2  whereby  the 
community  has  deliberately  sought  to  defend  particular 

trade,  and,  to  some  extent,  the  whole  manual  labor  class.  We  attribute  this 
characteristic  difference  between  the  English  middle  and  working  classes  largely 
to  the  feeling  of  the  weekly  wage-earner  that  he  is  dependent  for  the  continuity 
of  his  livelihood  on  circumstances  over  which  he  has  no  control,  and  that  he 
is,  by  the  modern  habit  of  engaging  and  dismissing  workmen  for  short  jobs, 
made  keenly  sensible  of  fluctuations  which  he  can  do  nothing  to  avert. 

1  Bentham,  Principles  of  the  Civil  Code,  part  i.  ch.  vii.     The  Whig  leaders 
in  1816  deprecated  any  discussion  by  the  House  of  Commons  of  sinecure  offices, 
and  even  of  excessive  salaries,  on  the  ground,  as  Francis  Homer  wrote  to  Lord 
Holland,  that  "it  is  a  ticklish  thing  to  begin  to  draw  subtle  distinctions  about 
property." — Memoirs  and  Correspondence  of  Francis  Horner^   M.P.    (London, 
1843),  vo1-  »•  P-  386. 

2  Principles  of  the  Law  of  Compensation^  by  C.  A.  Cripps,  Q.C.,  3rd  edition 
(London,  1892). 


568  Trade  Union  Function 

persons  or  classes  against  the  evil  effect  on  character  that 
ensues  on  finding  their  efforts  and  sacrifices  nullified  by 
circumstances  which  they  were  powerless  to  avert.  When 
we  remember  this  vast  network  of  defence,  built  up  during 
the  present  century  in  protection  of  the  security  and  continuity 
of  livelihood  of  brain-workers  and  property-holders,  it  is 
strange  that  it  is  just  these  classes  who  fail  to  comprehend 
the  weekly  wage-earner's  craving  for  the  same  boon.  "  An 
industrious  man,"  says  one  of  the  workmen's  spokesmen, 
"  having  learnt  a  trade,  or  enabled  by  any  honest  means  to 
earn  a  superior  living,  is  equally  entitled  to  an  adequate 
indemnity  if  his  trade  or  property  is  interfered  with,  or 
rendered  less  advantageous,  as  the  owner  of  a  water-mill, 
who  has  compensation  if  the  water  is  withdrawn.  Every 
description  of  property  has  ample  protection,  except  the 
poor  man's  only  property,  his  and  his  children's  industrious 
habits."1 

1  A  Comparative  Statement  of  the  Number  of  Laborers  employed  in  the  Execu- 
tion of  the  same  Quantity  of  Work  if  executed  by  Hand  or  Machine^  J.  Jarrold 
(Norwich,  1848).  Sismondi  pointed  out  in  1834  that  "to  make  a  true  calcula- 
tion of  what  society  gains  by  any  mechanical  invention  there  must  be  deducted 
from  it  the  loss  experienced  by  all  the  working  men  who  had  been  dismissed  by 
it,  till  they  have  found  an  employment  as  advantageous  as  the  one  they  had 
before." — "  On  Landed  Property,"  in  Revue  Mensuelle  d*  Economic  Politique, 
February  1834  ;  translated  in  his  Political  Economy  and  the  Philosophy  of 
Government  (London,  1837),  page  168. 

It  is  not  enough  to  assert,  as  is  often  done,  that  any  recognition  of  the 
workman's  vested  interest  in  his  trade  would  be  incompatible  with  the  industrial 
mobility  which  is  indispensable  to  modern  society.  The  community  cannot,  of 
course,  allow  the  vested  interest  of  any  individual  or  section  to  stand  in  the  way 
of  a  change  which  is  for  the  public  benefit.  This  admittedly  applies  to  all  vested 
interests,  whether  in  land,  personal  property,  public  offices,  or  anything  else. 
But  when  the  property  owner  or  the  holder  of  a  public  office  is  concerned,  the 
necessary  mobility  is  secured  without  inflicting  loss  on  the  individuals  affected, 
by  the  simple  device  of  pecuniary  compensation.  It  is  difficult  to  see  why  persons 
whose  occupations  are  "  injuriously  affected  "  by  a  railway  or  other  enterprise 
carried  out  by  Parliamentary  powers,  should  not  be  compensated  for  the  injury 
done  to  their  means  of  livelihood  in  the  same  way  as  the  landowner  is.  This 
claim  to  legislative  indemnity  of  displaced  workmen  was  recognised  by  J.  S.  Mill. 
The  social  advantage  derived  from  the  application  of  new  processes  and  machinery 
does  not,  he  declares,  "discharge  governments  from  the  obligation  of  alleviating, 
and,  if  possible,  preventing,  the  evils  of  which  this  source  of  ultimate  benefit  is  or 
may  be  productive  to  an  existing  generation  .  .  .  and  since  improvements  which 
do  not  diminish  employment  on  the  whole  almost  always  throw  some  particular 
class  out  of  it,  there  cannot  be  a  more  legitimate  object  of  the  legislator's  care 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          569 

But  although  the  philosophic  student  may  recognise  the 
common  origin  of  all  forms  of  "  vested  interest "  in  man's 
shrinking  from  the  great  social  evil  of  a  disappointment 
of  "  established  expectation,"  he  will  not  so  readily  admit 
the  virtue  of  the  panacea.  It  may  well  be  that,  as  applied 
to  particular  forms  of  personal  interest,  the  remedy  may 
bring  with  it  social  evils  greater  than  those  which  it  cures. 
Thus,  public  opinion  now  sides  with  Turgot  and  Adam 
Smith  in  their  denunciation  of  the  evil  effects  of  the  close 
corporations,  by  which  successive  generations  of  craftsmen 

than  the  interests  of  those  who  are  thus  sacrificed  to  the  gains  of  their  fellow- 
citizens  and  of  posterity  "  (Principles  of  Political  Economy,  by  J.  S.  Mill,  Book  I. 
chap.  vi.  sec.  3,  p.  62).  We  are  not  aware  of  any  case  in  which  this  humane 
principle  has  been  acted  upon.  It  is  true  that,  in  the  case  of  workmen  displaced 
by  an  invention,  it  would  neither  be  possible  nor  desirable  to  pay  them  lump  sums 
of  money.  But  if  they  are  willing  to  work  the  new  process,  there  seems  no 
equitable  reason  why  they  should  not  be  kept  on  at  their  former  wages,  even  at 
a  considerable  temporary  loss  to  the  community.  The  action  of  the  English 
legislature  in  awarding  compensation  for  disturbance  of  vested  interests  has, 
indeed,  been  capricious  in  the  extreme,  depending,  perhaps,  on  the  momentary 
political  influence  of  the  class  concerned.  Thus,  no  compensation  was  given  to 
the  large  class  of  lottery  keepers  and  their  servants,  either  for  loss  of  capital  or 
loss  of  occupation,  when  private  lotteries  were,  in  1698,  suddenly  prohibited.  The 
shipowners  and  merchants  who  had  invested  a  large  capital  in  specially  designed 
slave-carrying  ships  received  no  compensation  when  the  slave  trade  was  abolished 
in  1807.  On  the  other  hand,  when,  in  1834,  the  slaves  in  the  British  Colonies  were 
converted  into  indentured  servants,  twenty  millions  sterling  were  voted  to  the 
owners,  though  no  other  country,  before  or  after,  has  taken  this  course.  The 
owners  of  Irish  Parliamentary  Boroughs  were  compensated  when  the  Union 
deprived  them  of  these  seats,  but  the  owners  of  English  Parliamentary  Boroughs, 
which  had  equally  been  recognised  sources  of  income,  received  nothing  when  the 
Reform  Bill  of  1832  swept  them  away.  In  our  own  day,  when  a  Town  Council 
sets  up  its  own  works,  and  uses  public  funds  to  dispense  altogether  with  its  former 
contractors,  it  pays  them  no  compensation  for  loss  of  capital  or  livelihood.  But 
if  the  new  workshops  so  much  as  darken  the  view  from  the  contractor's  windows, 
the  town  must  pay  damages.  Parliament  gives  public  authorities  full  power  to 
ruin,  if  they  can,  the  private  owners  of  existing  gas-works  by  setting  up  public 
electric  lighting  works,  and  even  to  destroy  the  business  of  joint-stock  cemeteries 
by  starting  public  burial-grounds.  But  the  House  of  Commons  has  jealously 
refused  to  permit  any  Town  Council  to  put  up  gas-works  of  its  own,  whilst  any 
private  gas-works  are  in  the  field  as  opponents  ;  or  even  to  sink  its  own  wells  to 
get  a  new  and  entirely  different  supply  of  water  for  the  public,  without  first  fully 
compensating  any  existing  water  company,  not  for  taking  away  any  land,  works, 
or  water,  or  infringing  any  monopoly  rights,  but  simply  for  loss  of  income. 
Whether  the  holder  of  an  annually  granted  terminable  license  to  sell  intoxicating 
liquors  would  or  would  not  be  equitably  entitled  to  compensation  if  Parliament 
decided  for  the  future  not  to  renew  it,  is  a  hotly  contested  question. 


570  Trade  Union  Function 

were  legally  assured  of  a  customary  livelihood,  whether  they 
kept  pace  with  the  times,  or  jogged  along  contentedly  in 
the  old  routine.  In  exactly  the  same  strain  it  has  been 
urged  by  opponents  of  the  institution  of  private  property, 
that,  at  any  rate,  in  the  form  of  inherited  wealth,  it  over- 
reaches its  aim,  and  by  securing  a  livelihood  independent  of 
personal  exertion,  positively  counteracts  its  primary  purpose 
of  encouraging  each  generation  to  put  forth  its  fullest 
energies.  As  against  the  gilds,  modern  democracy  denies 
the  right  of  any  group  or  section  to  monopolise,  to  the 
exclusion  of  less  fortunate  outsiders,  any  opportunity  of 
public  service.  In  the  same  way  opponents  have  argued 
against  private  property  that,  by  creating  a  virtual  monopoly 
of  land  and  capital  in  the  hands  of  a  comparatively  small 
class,  the  right  of  exclusive  ownership  actually  hinders  whole 
sections  of  citizens  from  that  access  to  the  instruments  of 
production  by  which  alone  they  can  exercise  their  faculties. 
It  is  significant  that  almost  the  same  phrase — "  the  right  to 
work  " — was  used  by  Turgot  as  an  argument  against  the 
gilds,  and  by  Louis  Blanc  as  an  indictment  against  private 
property  in  capital  and  land.1 

It  was,  however,  not  these  general  arguments  that  in- 
duced Parliament  to  throw  over  the  vested  interests  of  the 
handicraftsmen.  Amid  the  rush  of  new  inventions,  a  legal 
"  right  to  a  trade,"  or  a  legal  limitation  of  apprentices,  whilst 
it  remained  an  irksome  restriction,  ceased  to  safeguard  the 
workman's  livelihood.  The  only  remedy  for  the  consequent 
disturbance  of  vested  interests  would  have  been  to  have 
stereotyped  the  existing  industrial  order,  by  the  absolute 
prohibition  of  machinery  or  any  other  innovation.  To  the 
statesman,  keen  on  securing  the  maximum  national  wealth, 
any  such  prohibition  appeared  suicidal.  To  the  new  class 
of  enterprising  captains  of  industry,  all  restrictions  stood  in 

1  "The  right  to  work  is  the  property  of  every  man,  and  this  property  is  the 
first,  the  most  sacred,  and  the  most  inalienable  of  all "  (Introduction  to  the  Law 
for  the  Suppression  of  "Jurandes,"  CEnvres  de  Tztrgot,  par  E.  Daire,  Paris,  1844, 
vol.  ii.  p.  306).  This  "droit  a  travailler  "  preceded  by  seventy  years  the  "droit 
an  travail  "  of  Louis  Blanc. 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          571 

the  way  of  that  free  use  of  their  capital  from  which  they 
could  derive  private  wealth.  The  dispossessed  craftsmen 
could  themselves  devise  no  feasible  alternative  to  laisser 
faire,  and  no  one  among  the  dominant  classes  thought  of 
any  means  of  compensation.  As  the  Industrial  Revolution 
progressed,  the  objection  to  any  interference  with  mobility 
increased  in  strength.  New  armies  of  workpeople  grew  up, 
without  vested  interests  of  their  own,  and  accordingly 
opposed  to  any  conception  of  society  which  excluded  them 
from  the  most  profitable  occupations.  Finally,  we  have  the 
rise  in  influence  of  the  great  body  of  consumers,  loth  to 
admit  that  the  disappointment  of  the  "  established  expecta- 
tion "  of  particular  sections  of  workers  is  any  adequate 
ground  for  refraining  from  the  cheapest  method  of  satisfying 
their  ever-changing  desires.  The  result  is  that  even  Trade 
Unionists  feel  the  Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests  to  be  out  of 
date.  It  is  still  held  with  fervor  by  the  more  conservative- 
minded  members  of  every  trade,  to  whom  it  fully  justifies 
such  restrictive  regulations  as  they  are  able  to  maintain.1  It 
is  naturally  strongest  in  the  remnants  of  the  time-honored 
ancient  handicrafts.  Those  who  have  troubled  to  explore 
the  nooks  and  crannies  of  the  industrial  world,  which  have 
hitherto  escaped  the  full  intensity  of  the  commercial  struggle, 
will  have  found  in  them  a  peculiar  type  of  Trade  Union 
character.  Wherever  the  Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests  .is 
still  maintained  by  the  workmen,  and  admitted  by  the 
employers — where,  that  is  to  say,  the  conditions  of  employ- 
ment are  consciously  based,  not  on  the  competitive  battle, 
but  on  the  established  expectations  of  the  different  classes — 
we  find  an  unusual  prevalence,  among  the  rank  and  file,  of 
what  we  may  call  the  "  gentle  "  nature — that  conjunction  of 
quiet  dignity,  grave  courtesy,  and  consideration  of  other 

1  Thus,  even  in  1897  we  find  an  aged  compositor  writing,  "It  is  useless 
saying  we  cannot  resist  the  machine.  I  say  we  can  and  must.  Are  we  to 
prostrate  ourselves  before  this  Juggernaut  of  a  'higher  civilisation,'  and  be 
crushed  out  of  existence  without  a  protest  ?  ...  To  live  by  his  own  industry  is 
every  man's  birthright,  and  whoever  attempts  to  curtail  that  right  is  a  traitor  to 
the  community." — Letter  in  Typographical  Circular,  February  1897. 


572  Trade  Union  Function 

people's  rights  and  feelings,  which  is  usually  connected  with 
old  family  and  long-established  position.  But  this  type  of 
character  becomes  every  day  rarer  in  the  Trade  Union 
world.  The  old  Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests  has,  in  fact, 
lost  its  vitality.  It  is  still  secretly  cherished  by  many 
workmen,  and  its  ethical  validity  is,  in  disputes  between 
different  Trade  Unions,  unhesitatingly  assumed  by  both 
sides.  But  we  no  longer  find  it  dominating  the  mind  of 
Trade  Union  leaders,  or  figuring  in  their  negotiations  with 
employers,  and  appeals  for  public  support.  Whatever  fate 
may  be  in  store  for  other  forms  of  vested  interests,  the 
modern  passion  for  progress,  demanding  the  quickest  possible 
adaptation  of  social  structure  to  social  needs,  has  effectually 
undermined  the  assumption  that  any  person  can  have  a 
vested  interest  in  an  occupation. 

When,  at  the  beginning  of  this  century,  the  Doctrine  of 
Vested  Interests  was,  as  regards  the  wage-earners,  definitely 
repudiated  by  the  House  of  Commons,  the  Trade  Unionists 
were  driven  back  upon  what  we  have  termed  the  Doctrine 
of  Supply  and  Demand.  Working  men  were  told,  by  friends 
and  foes  alike,  that  they  could  no  longer  be  regarded  as 
citizens  entitled  to  legal  protection  of  their  established  ex- 
pectations ;  that  labor  was  a  commodity  like  any  other  ; 
and  that  their  real  position  was  that  of  sellers  in  a  market, 
entitled  to  do  the  best  they  could  for  themselves  within  the 
limits  of  the  law  of  the  land,  but  to  no  better  terms  than 
they  could,  by  the  ordinary  arts  of  bargaining,  extract  from 
those  with  whom  they  dealt.  It  was  the  business  of  the 
employer  to  buy  "  labor "  in  the  cheapest  market,  and  that 
of  the  workman  to  sell  it  in  the  dearest.  It  followed  that 
the  only  criterion  of  justice  of  any  claim  was  ability  to  en- 
force it,  and  that  the  only  way  by  which  the  workmen  could 
secure  better  conditions  of  employment  was  by  strengthen- 
ing their  strategic  position  against  the  employer.  In  the 
History  of  Trade  Unionism  we  have  described  how,  after 
the  collapse  of  the  Owenite  Utopianism  of  1833-34,  this 
doctrine  came  as  a  new  spirit  into  the  Trade  Union  move- 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          573 

ment.  Thus  the  Flint  Glass  Makers,  whose  strong  and 
restrictive  combination  dates  from  1849,  have  avowedly 
based  their  whole  policy  upon  "  Supply  and  Demand." 
"When,"  wrote  their  chief  officer  in  1869,  "we  find  Mr. 
Nasmyth  explaining  [to  the  Royal  Commission  on  Trade 
Unions]  the  advantage  to  the  employer  of  a  supply  of 
surplus  labor,  it  is  easy  to  understand  the  consequences  to 
the  workmen  that  an  unlimited  supply  of  new  hands  might 
have  in  any  market,  and  their  objections  to  the  practice. 
That  the  State  should  enforce  any  such  limitation  would 
certainly  be  most  impolitic.  But  the  conduct  of  those  who 
refuse  to  work  under  a  system  of  an  unlimited  number  of 
apprentices  appears  to  us  precisely  similar  to  that  of  those 
employers  who  insist  on  it.  Both  parties  are  seeking  to  do 
the  best  for  their  own  interests,  and  neither  pretends  to 
consider  the  interests  of  those  whom  their  conduct  may 
affect.  The  masters  find  it  cheaper  to  employ  as  many 
boys  as  they  can,  and  they  leave  the  displaced  workmen  to 
their  own  resources.  The  men  on  their  side  find  it  their 
interest  to  decline  to  work  with  an  unrestricted  supply  of 
boys,  and  leave  the  unemployed  youth  to  do  the  best  they 
can  for  themselves.  The  employer  declines  all  responsibility 
as  to  the  consequences  of  displacing  a  number  of  middle- 
aged  workmen  by  boys,  on  the  ground  that  it  is  the  interest 
of  capital  to  find  the  cheapest  labor  it  can.  The  workmen 
find  it  is  the  interest  of  their  body  not  to  work  on  such 
terms.  In  this  battle  of  interest,  in  which  neither  party 
acknowledge  any  obligation  beyond  that  of  securing  their 
own  interests,  absolute  impartiality  appears  to  us  to  be  the 
only  safe  rule  of  the  State.  So  long  as  no  breach  of  the 
general  law  results,  and  no  legislative  restriction  exists,  the 
consequences  of  their  conduct  must  be  borne  by  each  party 
for  themselves." 1 

Between  1843  an^  1880  the  Doctrine  of  Supply  and 
Demand,  though  never  universally  accepted,  occupied  a 
dominant  place  in  the  minds  of  most  of  the  leaders  of  Trade 

1  Editorial  in  the  Flint  Glass  Makers'  Magazine,  vol.  vi.  No.  7  (March  1869). 


574  Trade  Union  Function 

Union  thought.  Viewed  in  the  light  of  the  workmen's  ex- 
perience of  the  evils  of  Individual  Bargaining,  and  of  the 
weakness  of  merely  local  unions,  it  meant  the  establishment 
of  strong  national  societies,  heaping  up  great  reserve  funds, 
and  seeking  to  control  the  supply  of  labor  in  a  whole 
industry  from  one  end  of  the  kingdom  to  the  other.  It 
involved,  moreover,  the  gradual  substitution  of  a  policy  of 
inclusion  for  that  of  exclusion.  Instead  of  jealously  restrict- 
ing Trade  Union  membership  to  men  who  had  "  earned  "  a 
right  to  the  trade  by  a  definite  apprenticeship  under  re- 
strictive conditions,  the  unions  came  more  and  more  to  use 
all  lawful  means  of  enforcing  membership  on  every  com- 
petent workman  whom  they  found  actually  working  at  their 
trade,  however  questionable  might  have  been  the  means  by 
which  he  had  acquired  his  skill.  The  policy  with  regard 
to  apprenticeship  underwent,  accordingly,  a  subtle  change. 
The  ideas  of  patrimony,  of  the  purchase  and  sale  of  "  the 
right  to  a  trade,"  and  of  a  traditional  ratio  between  learners 
and  adepts,  gradually  faded  away,  to  be  replaced  by  a  frank 
and  somewhat  cynical  policy  of  so  regulating  the  entrance 
to  an  industry  as  to  put  the  members  of  the  union  in  the 
best  possible  position  for  bargaining  with  the  employers. 
This  conscious  manipulation  of  the  labor  market,  the  direct 
outcome  of  the  Doctrine  of  Supply  and  Demand,  took 
different  forms  in  different  industries.  Among  the  Flint 
Glass  Makers,  for  instance,  it  led  to  an  absolutely  precise 
adjustment,  entrance  to  the  trade  and  progression  from  grade 
to  grade  being  so  regulated  as  instantly  to  fill  every 
vacancy  as  it  occurred,  but  so  as  to  leave  no  man  in  any 
grade  unemployed.  "  It  is,"  they  declared,  "  simply  a 
question  of  supply  and  demand,  and  we  all  know  that  if  we 
supply  a  greater  quantity  of  an  article  than  what  is  actually 
demanded,  that  the  cheapening  of  that  article,  whether  it  be 
labor  or  any  other  commodity,  is  a  natural  result." 1  The 
inference  was  a  strict  limitation  of  boy-labor.  "  Look  to 
the  rule  and  keep  boys  back  ;  for  this  is  the  foundation  of 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  p.   183. 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          575 

the  evil,  the  secret  of  our  progress,  the  dial  on  which  our 
society  works,  and  the  hope  of  future  generations."  l  The 
Cotton-spinners,  accepting  the  same  assumption  that  their 
wages  must  depend  exclusively  on  the  strength  of  their 
strategic  position  in  the  market,  find  that  exactly  the 
opposite  policy  is  the  best  suited  to  attain  their  end.  In- 
stead of  attempting  to  restrict  the  number  of  boys,  they 
insist  that  every  spinner  shall  be  attended  by  two  piecers,  a 
ratio  of  learners  to  adepts  ten  times  as  great  as  is  needed  to 
keep  up  the  supply.  This  regulation  is  insisted  on  in  all 
negotiations  with  the  employers,  expressly  on  the  ground 
that  only  by  such  an  arrangement  can  the  union  secure  for 
its  members  the  highest  possible  remuneration.2  But  the 
most  obvious  result  of  the  change  of  doctrine  was  a  revolu- 
tion in  policy  with  regard  to  wages  and  hours.  Under  the 
influence  of  the  Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests,  the  eighteenth- 
century  Trade  Unionists  had  confined  themselves,  in  the 
main,  to  protecting  their  customary  livelihood ;  asking 
advances,  therefore,  not  when  profits  were  large,  but  when 
the  cost  of  living  had  risen.  Under  the  influence  of  the 
view  that  wages  should  be  determined  by  the  strategic 
position  of  the  combined  wage-earners,  the  Trade  Unionists 
of  the  middle  of  the  present  century  boldly  asserted  a  claim, 
in  times  of  good  trade,  to  the  highest  possible  rates  that 
they  could  exact  from  employers  eager  to  fulfil  immensely 
profitable  orders.  Middle-class  public  opinion,  which  had 
accepted  as  inevitable  the  starvation  wages  caused  by 
Supply  and  Demand  in  the  lean  years,  was  shocked  in 
1872-73  at  the  rumor  of  coalminers  and  ironworkers,  in 
those  times  of  plenty,  demanding  ten  shillings  or  even  a 
pound  a  day,  and  faring  sumptuously  on  green  peas  and 
champagne.  The  great  captains  of  industry,  though  genuinely 
alarmed  at  the  Trade  Union  pretensions  to  share  in  the 

1  Flint  Glass  Makers'  Magazine,  September  1857;  History  of  Trade  Unionism, 
p.  184. 

2  For  the  economics  of  this  paradox — in  our  opinion  more  valid   than  the 
position  of  the  Flint  Glass  Makers — see  the  subsequent  chapter  on  "  The  Economic 
Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism." 


57°  Trade  Union  Function 

profits  of  good  times,  found  it  difficult  to  refuse  this 
application  of  their  own  Doctrine  of  Supply  and  Demand. 
We  find  them  accordingly  arranging,  particularly  in  the  coal 
and  iron  industries,  an  intellectual  compromise  with  the  Trade 
Union  leaders,  which  took  form  in  the  celebrated  device  of 
the  Sliding  Scale.  The  Durham  and  Northumberland  coal- 
owners,  and  the  North  of  England  iron-masters,  abandoned, 
once  for  all,  the  theory  that  wages  should  be  determined  by 
the  competition  of  individual  workmen  among  themselves, 
or  by  the  skill  in  bargaining  of  the  individual  employer. 
They  thus  frankly  conceded  the  central  position  of  Trade 
Unionism,  namely,  the  advantage  of  a  Common  Rule  co- 
extensive with  the  industry.  They  gave  up,  moreover,  any 
claim  to  take  advantage  of  the  glut  of  labor,  which  occurs 
from  time  to  time,  and  which,  under  the  Sliding  Scale,  is 
not  admitted  as  a  plea  for  any  reduction  of  wages.  The 
Trade  Unionists,  on  their  side,  agreed  to  forego  making  any 
use  of  the  occasional  short  supply  of  labor,  when  they 
might  otherwise  have  secured  an  advance.  But  they  also 
made  a  more  important  concession.  By  agreeing  that  the 
rate  of  wages  should  automatically  vary  with  the  price  of 
the  product,  they  accepted  the  employers'  contention  that 
the  workman's  income  should  be  determined  by  Supply  and 
Demand,  though  it  was  Supply  and  Demand  applied,  not 
directly  to  labor,  but  to  the  product  of  labor.  In  the  coal 
and  iron  trades,  the  selling  price  of  the  product,  as  fixed  by 
the  competitive  market,  was  taken  as  a  rough  index  of  the 
average  profitableness  of  the  industry  for  the  time  being.  Thus, 
the  workman's  position,  as  regards  his  proportion  of  the  pro- 
duct of  industry,  became  that  of  a  humble  partner.  But  he 
was  a  partner  without  any  share  in  the  management — with- 
out, in  particular,  any  voice  in  that  adjustment  of  the  amount 
of  production  to  the  intensity  of  demand,  upon  which  the 
selling  price  of  his  product,  and  therefore  his  livelihood, 
necessarily  depended.  Hence  the  cry  among  the  coal- 
miners  that  no  one  coal-owner  should  be  allowed,  by  reckless 
over-production,  to  depress  the  price  for  the  whole  trade, 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          577 

and  so  lower  both  profits  and  wages  all  round.  They  argued 
that,  if  the  daily  bread  of  half  a  million  miners'  households 
was  to  vary  automatically  with  the  price  of  coal — if  the 
workmen,  by  agreeing  to  a  Sliding  Scale,  were  to  forego 
their  right  to  fight  for  better  terms — then  the  fixing  of  the 
price,  as  against  the  consumer,  should  itself  form  a  part  of 
the  general  collective  agreement  upon  which  the  whole 
industry  depended.1  This  would  have  meant,  in  fact,  a 
gigantic  coal -trust  governed  by  a  joint  committee  of  capi- 
talists and  workmen,  regulating  output,  prices,  and  rates  of 
wages,  a  combination  which  British  coal-owners,  despite 
several  attempts,  have  hitherto  failed  to  establish.  The 
miners,  except  in  South  Wales,  have  therefore  abandoned 
the  Sliding  Scale,  and  have  now,  as  we  shall  presently 
describe,  come  under  the  influence  of  another  doctrine.2 

Meanwhile,  the  step  which  the  coal-owners  have  never 
been  able  to  take  has  been  taken  by  most  of  the  Birmingham 
metal  trades.  Since  1 890  a  remarkable  series  of  "  Alliances  " 
have  been  concluded  between  the  Employers'  Associations 
and  the  Trade  Unions  of  the  various  sections  of  the  staple 
industry  of  Birmingham,  based  on  the  idea  of  a  partnership 

1  See  our  chapter  on  "  Continuity  of  Employment "  for  a  description  of  the 
policy  of  restricting  output. 

2  The  fall  of  prices  since  1873,  to  whatever  cause  it  may  be  attributed,  would 
have  made  any  general  adoption  of  the  Sliding  Scale  disastrous  to  the  wage- 
earners.     Between  1867-77  (taken  as  par)  and    1896,   Mr.    Sauerbeck's  Index- 
Number,  representing  the  general  level  of  prices,  has  fallen  continuously  from 
100  to  6 1,  the  decline  having  no  relation  to  the  extent  of  business  or  to  the 
aggregate    employers'    profits,   both    of  which    are    much   greater  now  than  at 
any  former  period.     The  advocates  of  a  Sliding  Scale  contemplate,  it  is  true,  a 
periodical  revision  of  the  basis.      But  in  a  period  of  falling  prices,  the  onus  of 
making  the  change  would  always  be  on  the  wage-earners,  and  even  if  they  over- 
came this  serious  obstacle,  they  would  necessarily  stand  to  lose  so  long  as  each 
particular  basis  was  adhered  to.      In  a  period  of  rising  prices,  as,  for  instance, 
between    1850  and    1873,   the  employers  would  be  at  a  similar  disadvantage. 
The  fact  is  that,  whether  we  adopt  one  assumption  or  another,  the  rate  of  wages 
has  no  assignable  relation  to  the  fluctuations  in  the  price  of  the  product.     There 
seems  i,o  valid  reason  why  the  wage-earner  should  voluntarily  put  himself  in  a 
position  in  which  every  improvement  in  productive  methods,  every  cheapening 
of  the  cost  of  carriage,  every  advance  in  commercial  organisation,  every  lessening 
of  the  risks  of  business,  every  lightening  of  the  taxes  or  other  burdens  upon 
industry,  and  every  fall  in  the  rate  of  interest — all  of  which  are  calculated  to 
lower  price — should  automatically  cause  a  shrinking  of  his  wages. 

VOL.  II  2  P 


Trade  Union  Function 

between  employers  and  workmen  to  increase  the  profitableness 
of  the  trade  as  a  whole.1  The  terms  of  the  "  Alliance  "  be- 
tween "  the  Associated  Bedstead  and  Fender  Mount  Manu- 
facturers, and  those  operatives  (strip  casters,  stampers, 
spinners,  turners,  burnishers,  dippers,  and  solderers)  who  are 
members  of  the  Bedstead  and  Fender  Mount  (Operatives) 
Association,"  are  typical  of  all  these  agreements.  "  The  object 
of  the  Alliance  shall  be  the  improvement  of  selling  prices, 
and  the  regulation  of  wages  upon  the  basis  of  such  selling 
prices  .  .  .  thereby  securing  better  profits  to  manufacturers 
and  better  wages  to  workpeople."  To  secure  this  object  the 
employers  and  workmen  alike  agree  to  combine  against 
any  manufacturer  who  sells  below  the  agreed  price,  or 
attempts  to  reduce  wages.  "  This  understanding  shall 
include  a  pledge  on  the  part  of  the  manufacturers  not  to 
employ  any  but  association  workpeople  (over  21  years  of 
age),  excepting  by  special  arrangement  with  the  Operatives' 
Association,"  and  on  the  part  of  the  workmen  not  to  work 
for  any  but  those  manufacturers  who  sell  their  goods  at  such 
prices  as  are  from  time  to  time  decided  upon  by  "  a  Wages 
Board,  to  be  formed  of  an  equal  number  of  employers  and 
employed."  "  The  first  advances  of  prices  would  be 
recommended  to  the  Wages  Board  whenever  it  was  con- 
sidered safe  to  make  such  advance  .  .  .  that  is,  when  all 
.the  workpeople  have  joined  their  Association,  and  when  all 
the  manufacturers  have  agreed  together  to  sell  at  the  prices 
fixed  by  the  Employers'  Association.  .  .  .  The  bonus  paid 
to  the  members  of  the  Operatives'  Association  shall  be 
increased  at  the  rate  of  five  per  cent  advance  of  bonus  upon 
wages  for  every  ten  per  cent  advance  .  .  .  upon  present 

1  These  "  Alliances,"  which  form  a  significant  even  though  perhaps  a 
temporary  industrial  development,  have  elaborate  printed  agreements,  almost 
identical  in  their  terms.  Some  idea  of  the  spirit  underlying  them  may  be 
gathered  from  a  pamphlet,  The  New  Trades  Combination  Movement,  its  Principles 
and  Methods,  by  E.  J.  Smith  (Birmingham,  1895),  on  behalf  of  the  employers ; 
and  from  an  article  by  W.  J.  Davis  (Secretary  of  the  National  Society  of 
Amalgamated  Brassworkers)  in  the  Birmingham  and  District  Trades  Journal  for 
July  1896.  The  Birmingham  Daily  Post  for  the  years  1895-96  contains  many 
articles  and  letters  on  the  subject. 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          579 

selling  prices  "  (irrespective  of  changes  in  the  market  price  of 
metal  as  the  raw  material). 

We  have  in  these  Birmingham  "  Alliances,"  of  which 
half  a  dozen  have  lately  sprung  into  existence,  an  ex- 
ceptionally developed  manifestation  of  the  doctrine  that  the 
conditions  of  employment  should  be  left  to  Supply  and 
Demand,  or,  to  put  it  in  another  way,  should  correspond  to 
the  relative  strategic  position  of  the  parties  to  the  bargain. 
Each  party  naturally  does  its  best,  within  the  limits  '  of  the 
law,  to  improve  its  own  position  in  the  market.  The  work- 
men, rinding  themselves  individually  powerless  to  stand  out 
for  better  terms,  combine  in  order  to  strengthen  themselves 
against  the  employers.  The  employers,  on  their  side,  combine 
to  protect  themselves  against  the  workmen.  Finally  both 
parties,  discovering  no  other  way  of  maintaining  the  price  of 
their  product,  upon  which  both  wages  and  profits  are  deemed 
to  depend,  unite  their  forces  in  order  to  exact  better  terms 
from  the  community  for  the  trade  as  a  whole,  and  incidentally 
to  protect  themselves  against  what  they  choose  to  consider 
the  unfair  competition  of  a  few  individuals  among  them.  Nor 
is  such  an  alliance  either  so  new  or  so  unique  as  might  be 
supposed.  The  imperfect  organisation  of  employers  and 
workmen  alike,  and  the  absence  of  a  mutual  understanding 
between  them,  has  hitherto  stood  in  the  way  of  the  adoption 
of  formal  or  elaborate  treaties  of  this  nature.  But  a  tacit 
assumption,  acted  on  by  both  employers  and  workmen,  may, 
in  some  industries,  be  as  effective  in  keeping  up  prices  and 
excluding  competitors  as  a  published  treaty.  Thus,  the 
uniformly  friendly  relations  between  the  little  group  of  manu- 
facturers of  hand-made  paper,  and  the  union  of  the  skilled 
handicraftsmen  employed,  are  certainly  maintained  by  a  half- 
conscious  compact  to  hinder  new  competitors  from  entering 
the  trade.1  And  in  such  trades  as  the  Plumbers,  Basket- 

1  Thus,  the  employers  have  long  allowed  the  union  to  limit  most  strictly  the 
number  of  apprentices,  even  to  the  point  of  there  being  "not  a  spare  hand  in  the 
trade."  The  workmen  have  frequently  pointed  out  how  well  this  suits  the 
interests  of  the  present  employers,  alleging  that  "  it  would  be  a  great  inducement 


580  Trade  Union  Function 

makers,  and  many  others,  it  is  common  to  find,  in  the 
"  Working  Rules,"  or  even  in  the  constitution  of  the  Trade 
Union,  a  regulation  inserted  at  the  instance  of  the  employers 
which  prohibits  or  penalises  work  being  done  directly  for 
ihe_canstHftei7-er  for  any  class  of  employers  who  might 
become  the  business  rivals  of  those  who  have  entered  into 
the  agreement. 

We  see,  therefore,  that  the  Doctrine  of  Supply  and 
Demand  differs  in  the  most  practical  way  from  the  Doctrine 
of  Vested  Interests.  Instead  of  being  inconsistent  with  the 
facts  of  modern  industry,  it  seems  capable  of  indefinite 
development  to  meet  the  changing  conditions  of  the  world- 
commerce.  Far  from  being  antagonistic  to  the  business  spirit 
of  the  present  century,  it  falls  in  with  the  assumption  that 
the  highest  interests  of  Humanity  are  best  attained  by 
every  one  pursuing  what  he  conceives  to  be  his  own  interest 
in  the  manner,  within  the  limits  of  the  law  of  the  land,  that 
he  thinks  best  for  himself.  It  is,  moreover,  merely  applying 
to  the  relations  of  capital  and  labor  the  principles  which 
already  govern  the  business  relations  of  commercial  men  to 
each  other.  Whether  the  capitalist  can  bargain  individually 
with  his  workpeople,  or  is  forced  by  their  combination  to 
deal  with  them  collectively,  the  Doctrine  of  Supply  and 
Demand  seems  to  put  the  matter  on  a  strictly  business 
footing.  The  relation  between  employer  and  wage-earner, 
like  that  between  buyer  and  seller,  becomes,  in  fact,  merely 
an  incident  in  the  "  beneficent  private  war  which  makes  one 
man  strive  to  climb  on  the  shoulders  of  another  and  remaifK 
there."  l  Seen  in  this  light,  the  unsystematic  inequality, 
which  is  the  result  of  the  modern  industrial  struggle,  has 


for  capital  to  enter  the  trade  if  labor  could  be  got,"  but  that  the  Trade  Union 
regulations  made  the  "vat  trade,"  in  effect,  "a  close  corporation.  .  .  .  There 
has  long  been  a  mutual  agreement  between  the  two  parties.  .  .  .  There  have 
been  little  disputes  from  time  to  time,  no  doubt,  but  they  have  been  more  in  the 
nature  of  family  jars  than  anything  else."  —  Arbitration  on  the  Question  of  an 
Advance  in  Wages  .  .  .,  Rupert  Kettle,  Esq.,  Q.C.,  Arbitrator  (Maidstone,  1874), 
p.  64. 

1   Poptdar  Government,  by  Sir  Henry  Maine  (London,  1885),  p.  50. 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          585 

as  to  bring  the  actual  hours  of  work  within  what  the  Board 
may  consider  to  be  "  reasonable  limits,"  and  may  compel 
compliance  with  the  revised  schedule  under  penalty  of  a  fine 
not  exceeding  a  hundred  pounds  a  day.1  To  the  vast 

1  The  average  public  opinion  of  the  propertied  classes  on  these  points  has 
been  well  expressed  by  the  Right  Hon.  Sir  Lyon  (now  Lord)  Playfair,  F.R.S.,  in 
his  essay  On  the  Wages  and  Hours  of  Labor  (London,  1892;  published  by  the 
Cobden  Club).  "It  is  to  the  interest  of  all  of  us  that  the  weak  should  be  pro- 
tected against  the  strong ;  and  hence  it  is  right  to  enact  factory  laws  to  regulate 
the  hours  of  labor  for  women  and  children,  and  these  react  without  law  in 
shortening  the  hours  of  labor  of  men.  Children  are  the  growing  generation  of 
men  and  women,  and  their  labor  should  be  of  a  kind  that  will  not  stunt  their 
growth.  True,  women  may  be  adults  [why  "may"?];  and  why  should  we 
class  them  with  children  ?  Because  it  is  to  the  interest  of  all  of  us  that  female 
labor  should  be  limited  so  as  not  to  injure  the  motherhood  and  family  life  of  a 
nation.  .  .  .  It  is  to  the  interests  of  all  of  us  that  work  should  be  carried  on  in 
normal  conditions  of  health,  so  that  workshops  should  not  maim  or  stunt 
humanity.  It  is  not  in  the  power  of  individual  workmen  to  protect  themselves 
from  defective  machinery  or  bad  ventilation ;  so  it  is  in  the  interests  of  all  of  us 
to  make  laws  for  their  preservation  from  preventable  causes  of  mortality."  Lord 
Playfair  then  proceeds  to  denounce  any  interference  by  the  State  with  regard  to 
the  hours  of  labor  or  wages  of  adult  men,  on  the  grounds  (i)  "that  it  would 
be  impossible  for  the  State  to  intervene  in  the  management  of  trade,  because,  if 
it  did  so,  it  becomes  responsible  for  the  success  or  failure  of  each  particular 
undertaking,"  and  (2)  "  that  it  is,  not  a  theory,  but  a  law  of  economics  surely 
established,  that  decline  and  degradation  follow  the  loss  of  self-activity."  Lord 
Playfair  nowhere  explains  why  these  arguments  do  not  equally  negative  any 
State  interference  with  the  hours  of  adult  women,  or  any  legal  prescription  of 
elaborate  and  costly  sanitary  provisions  in  factories  containing  only  adult  men. 
Nor  does  he  explain  why  the  same  assumption  of  general  wellbeing,  upon  which 
'•<e  ;ustifies  State  interference  with  adult  women's  hours  and  adult  men's  water- 
sets,  would  not  equally  justify  State  interference  with  adult  women's  wages 
and  adult  men's  hours.  The  whole  essay  is  full  of  similar  jumps  from,  one 
hypothesis  to  another,  without  warning  to  the  reader,  or  explanation  of  the 
reason  for  the  substitution.  It  is,  in  fact,  a  remarkable  instance  of  the  manner  in 
which  even  a  man  trained  in  one  science  will,  in  dealing  with  the  subject  matter 
of  another  in  which  he  has  had  no  systematic  training,  use  the  logic  of  the  un- 
educated. It  is  therefore  not  surprising  that,  in  the  very  next  year  after  this 
authoritative  deliverance  against  any  State  interference  with  the  hours  of  adult 
men,  it  was  Lord  Playfair  himself  who  piloted  through  the  House  of  Lords  the 
bill  empowering  the  Board  of  Trade  peremptorily  to  stop  excessive  hours  of 
labor  among  railway  servants,  and  who  even  resisted  an  amendment  to  confine 
the  scope  of  this  protective  measure  to  persons  engaged  with  the  movement  of 
traffic  (House  of  Lords  Journals,  vol.  cxxv.  1893).  Lord  Playfair  has,  so  far  as 
we  know,  not  yet  explained  why  this  State  intervention  in  the  complicated 
railway  industry  has  not  made  the  Government  "  responsible  for  the  success  or 
failure  of  each  particular  undertaking"  ;  nor  yet  why  "decline  and  degradation" 
has  not  followed  "the  loss  of  self-activity"  among  the  railway  servants.  The  change 
of  attitude  in  England  with  regard  to  regulation  of  the  hours  of  railway  servants 
has  been  elaborately  analysed  by  Professor  Gustav  Cohn  in  two  articles  on  "  Die 


586  Trade  Union  Function 

majority  of  Trade  Unionists  the  intellectual  assumption  on 
which  Parliament  has  acted  with  regard  to  the  hours  of 
women  and  railway  servants  appears  to  apply  all  round. 
The  average  Trade  Unionist  unconsciously  takes  it  for 
granted  that  the  hours  of  labor,  whether  fixed  by  Collective 
Bargaining  or  Legal  Enactment,  ought  to  be  settled  without 
reference  to  the  momentary  strategic  position  of  the  section 
concerned.  We  have  already  noticed  that,  with  one  or  two 
remarkable  exceptions,  the  richer  and  more  powerful  sections 
of  the  wage-earners  put  forward  no  claim  to  shorter  hours  of 
labor  than  those  enjoyed  by  their  less  advantageously  placed 
colleagues,  and  that  the  successive  requests  for  shorter  hours 
have  usually  formed  part  of  contemporary  general  movements 
extending  from  one  end  of  the  Trade  Union  world  to  the 
other,  and  based  on  the  plea  that  the  shorter  working  day 
proposed  was  desirable  in  the  interests  of  physical  health 
and  civic  efficiency. 

When  we  pass  from  the  circumstances  amid  which  the 
wage-earner  is  to  work,  and  the  number  of  hours  which  he 
must  spend  in  labor,  to  the  amount  of  money  which  he  will 
receive  as  wages,  we  find  the  protest  against  the  Doctrine  of 
Supply  and  Demand  much  less  universal,  and  only  recently 
becoming  conscious  of  itself.  During  the  whole  of  this 
century  middle-class  public  opinion  has  scouted  the  idea  that 
the  actual  money  wages  of  the  operative  could  possibly  be 
governed  by  any  other  considerations  than  the  relative 
strategic  positions  of  the  parties  to  the  bargain.  And 
although  the  Trade  Unionists  have  never  thoroughly  ac- 
cepted this  doctrine,  even  when  that  of  Vested  Interests  had 
become  manifestly  impossible,  they  have,  until  recent  years, 
never  succeeded  in  intelligibly  setting  forth  any  contrary 
view.  No  reader  of  the  working-class  literature  for  the  last 
two  hundred  years  can,  however,  doubt  the  existence  of  an 
abiding  faith  in  quite  another  principle.  Deep  down  in 
their  hearts  the  organised  workmen,  even  whilst  holding  the 

Arbeitszeit  der  Englischen  Eisenbahnbediensten,"  in  the  Archiv  fur  Eisenbahn- 
wesen  for  1892  and  1893  respectively. 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          587 

Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests,  or  acquiescing  in  that  of  Supply 
and  Demand,  have  always  cherished  a  feeling  that  one  condi- 
tion is  paramount  over  all,  namely,  that  wages  must  be  so 
fixed  that  the  existing  generation  of  operatives  should  at  any 
rate  be  able  to  live  by  their  trade.  "We  ask,"  say  the 
United  Silk  Throwers  in  1872,  "for  a  fair  day's  wages  for  a 
fair  day's  work.  .  .  .  What  is  a  fair  day's  wage  ?  Brethren, 
...  no  one  can  deny  it,  the  due  reward  for  our  labor  may  be 
summed  up  in  these  words,  Shelter,  Food,  and  Raiment  both 
for  ourselves,  our  wives,  and  our  children."  l  Throughout  all 
the  negotiations  about  Sliding  Scales,  we  see  constantly 
emanating  from  the  rank  and  file  of  the  operatives  the 
demand  that  the  Scale  should  begin  from  a  minimum  below 
which  wages  could  under  no  circumstances  be  reduced.  In 
this  they  had  the  support  of  the  ablest  working-class  thinker 
of  the  time.  "The  first  thing,"  wrote  Lloyd  Jones  in  1874, 
"that  those  who  manage  trade  societies  should  settle  is  a 
minimum  which  they  should  regard  as  a  point  below  which 
they  should  never  go.  ...  Such  a  one  as  will  secure  suffici- 
ency of  food,  and  some  degree  of  personal  and  home  comfort 
to  the  worker  ;  not  a  miserable  allowance  to  starve  on,  but 
living  wages.  The  present  agreements  they  are  going  into, 
on  fluctuating  market  prices,  is  a  practical  placing  of  their 
fate  in  the  hands  of  others.  It  is  throwing  the  bread  of 
their  children  into  a  scramble  of  competition,  where  every- 
thing is  decided  by  the  blind  and  selfish  struggles  of  their 
employers." 2  "I  entirely  agree,"  wrote  Professor  Beesly, 
"  with  an  admirable  article  by  Mr.  Lloyd  Jones  in  a  recent 
number  of  the  Beehive^  in  which  he  maintained  that  colliers 
should  aim  at  establishing  a  minimum  price  for  their  labor, 

1  Preface  to  Rules  of  the  United  Silk  Throwers'  Trade  and  Friendly  Society , 
"commenced  24th  October  1868"  (Derby,    1872).      In  the  Practical  Uses  and 
Remarks  on  the  Articles  of  the  Operative  Colliers  of  Lanark,  Dumbarton,  and 
Renfrewshire  (Glasgow,  1825),  a  pamphlet  preserved  in  the  Place  MSS.  (27,805), 
the  phrase  occurs,   "our  aim  is  lawfully  to  obtain  a  bare  living  price  for  our 
arduous  labor." 

2  "  Should  Wages  be  Regulated  by  Market  Price  ?  "  Beehive,  i8th  July  1874  ; 
see  also  his  article  in  the  issue  for  4th   March   1874,   anr^   History  of  Trade 
Unionism,  pp.  325-327. 


588  Trade  Union  Function 

and  compelling  their  employers  to  take  this  into  account  as 
the  one  constant  and  stable  element  in  all  their  speculations. 
All  workmen  should  keep  their  eyes  fixed  on  this  ultimate 
ideal."  l  For  fifteen  years  this  idea  of  a  "  Living  Wage " 
simmered  in  the  minds  of  Trade  Unionists.  The  labor  up- 
heaval of  1889  marked  its  definite  adoption  as  a  fundamental 
assumption  of  Trade  Unionism,  in  conscious  opposition  both 
to  the  Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests  and  to  that  of  Supply 
and  Demand.  The  Match  Girls  had  no  vested  interests  to 
appeal  to,  and  Supply  and  Demand,  to  the  crowd  of  hungry 
laborers  struggling  at  the  dock  gates,  meant  earnings  abso- 
lutely inconsistent  with  industrial  efficiency.  The  General 
Manager  of  one  of  the  dock  companies  himself  admitted  the 
fact.  "  The  very  costume,"  he  told  the  House  of  Lords,  in 
which  the  dock  laborers  "  presented  themselves  to  the  work 
prevents  them  doing  work.  The  poor  fellows  are  miserably 
clad,  scarcely  with  a  boot  on  their  foot,  in  a  most  miserable 
state;  and  they  cannot  run,  their  boots  would  not  permit  them. 
.  .  .  There  are  men  who  come  on  to  work  in  our  docks  (and 
if  with  us,  to  a  much  greater  extent  elsewhere)  who  come  on 
without  having  a  bit  of  food  in  their  stomachs,  perhaps 
since  the  previous  day  ;  they  have  worked  for  an  hour  and 
have  earned  5d. ;  their  hunger  will  not  allow  them  to  con- 
tinue ;  they  take  the  $d.  in  order  that  they  may  get  food, 
perhaps  the  first  food  they  have  had  for  twenty-four  hours. 
Many  people  complain  of  dock  laborers  that  they  will  not 
work  after  four  o'clock.  But  really,  if  you  only  consider  it, 
it  is  natural.  These  poor  men  come  on  work  without  a 
farthing  in  their  pockets ;  they  have  not  anything  to  eat  in 
the  middle  of  the  day ;  some  of  them  will  raise  or  have  a 
penny,  and  buy  a  little  fried  fish,  and  by  four  o'clock  their 
strength  is  utterly  gone ;  they  pay  themselves  off ;  it  is 
absolute  necessity  which  compels  them.  .  .  .  Many  people 
complain  of  their  not  working  after  four,  but  they  do  not 
know  the  real  reason."  2  The  result,  in  fact,  of  leaving  wages 

1  Beehive,  i6th  May  1874  ;  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  p.  326. 

2  Evidence  before  House  of  Lords  Committee  on  the  Sweating  System  ;   The 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          589 

to  be  settled  solely  by  the  relative  strategic  positions  of  the 
parties  to  the  bargain  is  to  drive  whole  sections  of  the  popu- 
lation to  accept  earnings  so  low,  and  so  irregularly  discon- 
tinuous, as  to  be  wholly  insufficient  for  the  maintenance  of 
any  muscular  strength.  It  was,  we  think,  this  unexpected 
discovery,  made  by  the  House  of  Lords  Committee  on 
Sweating,  and  by  Mr.  Charles  Booth  and  his  colleagues,  that 
brought  public  opinion  to  the  aid  of  the  strikers  of  1889, 
and  compelled  the  employers  to  yield,  at  any  rate  for  the 
moment,  to  demands  which  neither  the  Match  Girls  nor  the 
Dockers  had  any  power  to  obtain  by  the  strength  of  their 
own  combinations. 

Four  years  later  the  same  assumption  gained  world-wide 
celebrity  under  Lloyd  Jones's  own  phrase  of  a  "  Living  Wage." 
When  the  members  of  the  Miners'  Fedexatioft-wciu  menaced, 
in  the  trade  contraction  of  1892-93,  with  a  serious  reduction 
of  wages,  they  definitely  repudiated  the  Doctrine  of  Supply 
and  Demand,  and  maintained  their  right,  whatever  the  state 
of  trade,  to  a  minimum  sufficient  to  secure  their  efficiency  as 
producers  and  citizens.  "  They  held  it  as  a  matter  of  life 
and  death,"  said  the  Vice-President  of  the  Miners'  Federation 
in  1892,  "that  any  condition  of  trade  ought  to  warrant  the 
working  man  living.  They  held  that  it  was  a  vital  principle 
that  a  man  by  his  labor  should  live,  and  notwithstanding 
all  the  teachings  of  the  political  economists,  all  the  doctrines 
taught  by  way  of  supply  and  demand,  they  said  there  was  a 
greater  doctrine  over-riding  all  these,  and  that  was  the 
doctrine  of  humanity.  They  believed  that  the  working-man 
was  worthy  of  his  hire,  and  held  at  the  present  moment  that 
wages  were  as  low  as  they  ever  ought  to  be."  *  "  We  have 
come  to  the  conclusion,"  repeated  the  President  of  the  same 
organisation  in  1894,  "that  prior  to  1887  the  men  were  not 
earning  a  living  wage,  that  is,  they  had  not  sufficient  wage  at 

Story  of  the  Dockers*  Strike,  by  Llewellyn  Smith  and  Vaughan  Nash  (London, 
1889),  p.  47. 

1  Speech  of  Sam  Woods,    M.P.,  at  the  Annual  Conference  of  the  Miners' 
Federation  of  Great  Britain,  held  at  Hanley,  January  1892,  pp.  9-10. 


59°  Trade  Union  Function 

the  end  of  the  week  to  properly  feed  and  clothe  their 
children  and  pay  their  way  in  the  world.  We  think  that 
thirty  per  cent  added  on  to  the  rate  of  wages  then  paid  will 
secure  to  the  men  what  we  believe  to  be  the  rate  of  wages 
which  will  consummate  that  desirable  object."  l 

We  can  now  form  a  definite  idea  of  the  assumption 
which  this  generation  has  set  up  against  the  Doctrine  of 
Supply  and  Demand,  and  which  we  have  termed  the  Doctrine 
of  a  Living  Wage.  There  is  a  growing  feeling,  not  confined 
to  Trade  Unionists,  that  the  best  interests  of  the  community 
can  only  be  attained  by  deliberately  securing,  to  each  section 
of  the  workers,  those  conditions  which  are  necessary  for  the 
continuous  and  efficient  fulfilment  of  its  particular  function  in 
the  social  machine.  From  this  point  of  view,  it  is  immaterial 
to  the  community  whether  or  not  a  workman  has,  by  birth, 
servitude,  or  purchase,  acquired  a  "  right  to  a  trade,"  or  what, 
at  any  given  moment,  may  be  his  strategic  position  towards 
the  capitalist  employer.  The  welfare  of  the  community  as  a 
whole  requires,  it  is  contended,  that  no  section  of  workers 
should  be  reduced  to  conditions  which  are  positively  incon- 
sistent with  industrial  or  civic  efficiency.  Those  who  adopt 
this  assumption  argue  that,  whilst  it  embodies  what  was  good 
in  the  two  older  doctrines,  it  avoids  their  socially  objection- 
able features.  Unlike  the  Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests,  it 
does  not  involve  any  stereotyping  of  industrial  processes,  or 
the  protection  of  any  class  of  workers  in  the  monopoly  of  a 
particular  service.  It  is  quite  consistent  with  the  freedom 
of  every  wage-earner  to  choose  or  change  his  occupation,  and 
with  the  employer's  freedom  to  take  on  whichever  man  he 
thinks  best  fitted  for  his  work.  Thus  it  in  no  way  checks 
mobility  or  stops  competition.  Unlike  the  Doctrine  of 
Supply  and  Demand  it  does  not  tempt  the  workmen  to  limit 
their  numbers,  or  combine  with  the  employers  to  fix  prices, 

1  Private  Minnies  of  Proceedings  at  a  Joint  Conference  between  Representa- 
tives of  the  Federated  Coal-owners  and  the  Miners1  Federation  of  Great  Britain  and 
Ireland,  Lord  Shand  in  the  Chair  (London,  1894);  speech  of  Mr.  B.  Pickard, 
M.P.,  p.  17. 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          591 

or  restrict  output.  It  avoids,  too,  the  evil  of  fluctuations 
of  wages,  in  which  the  income  of  the  workers  varies,  not 
according  to  their  needs  as  citizens  or  producers,  nor  yet  to 
the  intensity  of  their  exertion,  but  solely  according  to  the 
temporary  and,  as  far  as  they  are  concerned,  fortuitous 
position  of  their  trade.  On  the  other  hand,  the  Doctrine  of 
a  Living  Wage  goes  far  in  the  direction  of  maintaining 
"  established  expectation."  Whilst  it  includes  no  sort  of 
guarantee  that  any  particular  individual  will  be  employed  at 
any  particular  trade,  those  who  are  successful  in  the  com- 
petition may  feel  assured  that,  so  long  as  they  retain  their 
situations,  the  conditions  of  an  efficient  and  vigorous  working 
life  will  be  secured  to  them.1 

The  most  obvious  drawback  of  the  Doctrine  of  a  Living 
Wage  is  its  difficulty  of  application.  There  is,  to  begin  with, 
a  loss  of  theoretical  perfection  in  the  fact  that  the  indispens- 
able minimum  conditions  prescribed  for  each  occupation 
cannot  practically  be  adapted  to  the  requirements  of  each 
individual,  but  must  be  roughly  gauged  by  needs  of  the 
normal  type.  It  may  well  be  that  a  consumptive  weaver  or 
a  short-sighted  engineer  requires,  for  his  continued  preserva- 
tion, atmospheric  conditions  or  elaborate  fencing  of  machinery 
which  would  be  wasted  on  the  vast  majority  of  his  colleagues. 
It  might  be  found  that  an  exceptionally  delicate  girl  ought 
not  to  work  more  than  five  hours  a  day,  or  that  a  somewhat 
backward  laborer  with  a  sick  wife  and  a  large  family  could 
not  maintain  himself  in  physical  efficiency  on  the  standard 
wages  of  his  class.  But  this  is  not  a  practical  objection. 
The  prescription  of  certain  minimum  conditions  does  not 
prevent  the  humane  employer  from  voluntarily  granting  to 
any  exceptionally  unfortunate  individuals  for  whom  the 
minimum  is  insufficient  whatever  better  terms  are  physically 

1  Thus  the  Doctrine  of  a  Living  Wage  does  not  profess,  any  more  than  does  the 
Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests  or  that  of  Supply  and  Demand,  to  solve  the  problem 
of  the  unemployed  or  the  unemployable.  All  three  doctrines  are  obviously 
consistent  with  any  treatment  of  that  problem,  from  leaving  the  unemployed  and 
the  unemployable  to  starvation  or  mendicancy,  up  to  the  most  scientific  Poor 
Law  classification,  or  the  most  complete  system  of  state  or  trade  insurance.  • 


59 2  Trade  Union  Function 

possible.  What  it  does  prevent  is  the  taking  advantage  of 
the  strategic  weakness  of  such  individuals,  and  their  being 
compelled  to  accept  positively  worse  conditions  of  employ- 
ment than  their  stronger  colleagues.  A  more  serious 
difficulty  is  our  lack  of  precise  knowledge  as  to  what  are  the 
conditions  of  healthy  life  and  industrial  efficiency.  In  the 
matter  of  sanitation  this  difficulty  has,  within  the  past  fifty 
years,  been  largely  overcome.  With  regard  to  the  proper 
limits  to  be  set  to  the  duration  of  toil,  we  are  every  year 
gaining  more  information  from  the  doctors  and  the  physio- 
logists, and  a  Select  Committee,  called  upon  to  decide  upon 
evidence  the  maximum  working  day  consistent,  in  any 
particular  industry,  with  the  healthy  existence,  home  life, 
and  citizenship  of  the  average  workman,  would  arrive,  with- 
out much  difficulty,  at  a  reasonable  decision.  The  case  is 
very  different  with  regard  to  wages.  There  are  practically 
no  scientific  data  from  which  we  can  compute  the  needs  of 
particular  occupations.  The  customary  standards  of  life 
differ  from  class  to  class  to  such  an  extent  as  to  bear  no  dis- 
coverable relation  to  the  waste  and  repair  involved  in  the 
respective  social  functions  of  the  various  grades.  It  would, 
it  is  true,  be  possible  for  our  imaginary  Select  Committee  to 
come  to  some  definite  conclusion  as  to  the  amount  of  food 
stuffs,  clothing,  and  house  accommodation,  without  which  no 
family  could,  in  town  and  country  respectively,  be  maintained 
in  full  physical  and  mental  health.  But  directly  we  compare 
the  muscular  exhaustion  of  the  steel-smelter,  plater,  or  flint 
glass  maker,  with  the  intensity  of  mental  application  of  the 
cotton-spinner,  engraver,  or  linotype  operator,  we  have  as 
yet  no  data  from  which  to  estimate  the  cost  of  the  extra 
food,  clothing,  and  recreation  called  for  by  the  greater  waste 
of  muscle  and  nerve  of  any  of  these  sections,  over  that 
incurred  by  the  day  laborer  or  the  railway  porter.  And 
even  if  we  could  come  to  some  conclusion  as  to  the  "  normal 
ration  "  required  to  keep  each  trade  in  health,  we  should  still 
be  unable  to  decide  how  much  must  be  added  in  each  case 
to  gompersate  for  irregularity  of  employment.  The  stone- 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism         593 

masons  and  the  painters,  who  are  rendered  idle  at  every 
frost,  the  boilermakers  and  the  engineers,  subject  to  the 
intense  fluctuations  of  speculative  shipbuilding,  are  in  a  very 
different  position  from  the  railway  servants  and  municipal  em- 
ployees, whose  weekly  incomes  are  practically  uninterrupted. 
There  is  yet  another  difficulty.  If  special  wages  were  fixed 
to  meet  the  special  needs  of  particular  trades,  neither  the 
employer  nor  the  community  would  have  any  guarantee  that 
the  extra  sum  allowed  would  be  spent  in  extra  nourishment, 
proper  recreation,  or  insurance  against  periods  of  unemploy- 
ment. Nor  are  the  better-paid  sections  of  the  wage-earners 
at  all  prepared  for  any  such  application  of  the  Doctrine  of  a 
Living  Wage.  All  the  industries  in  which  the  Trade  Unions 
have  succeeded  in  so  controlling  the  conditions  of  employ- 
ment as  to  secure  exceptional  rates  of  payment  would 
naturally  object  to  any  departure  from  the  Doctrine  of 
Supply  and  Demand.  The  plater  or  rivetter,  earning  in 
good  times  a  pound  a  day,  is  quite  alive  to  the  fact  that  so 
large  alrtn^orne~cannarte  proved  to  be  required  to  main- 
tain him  in  full  efficiency,  especially  when  he  realises  how 
considerable  a  sum  is  actually  spent  by  the  "  average  sensual 
man  "  in  his  class  on  gambling  and  drink.  And,  under  the 
capitalist  system,  his  reluctance  to  give  up  his  position  of 
advantage  is  justified  by  the  fact,  that  whatever  was  saved 
in  wages  would  merely  swell  the  incomes  of  the  brain- 
workers  and  shareholders,  whose  personal  expenditure,  and 
that  of  their  wives,  seem  to  him  even  more  anarchic  and 
wasteful  than  that  of  the  ordinary  working-class  family.1 
All  these  considerations  unite  to  make  public  opinion  slow  to 
apply  to  money  wages  the  assumption  already  acted  on  with 
regard  to  the  sanitary  conditions  of  employment,  and  to  a 
large  extent  accepted  with  regard  to  the  hours  of  labor.  We 

1  There  are  sound  reasons  of  public  policy,  as  we  shall  attempt  to  show  in 
our  chapter  on  "The  Economic  Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism,"  why  the 
better-paid  sections  should  not  forego  their  superior  incomes.  The  Doctrine  of 
a  Living  Wage,  though,  as  we  shall  demonstrate,  valid  as  far  as  regards  the  estab- 
lishment of  a  minimum  Common  Rule,  does  not  supply  a  complete  theory  of  dis- 
tribution. 

VOL.  II  2  Q 


594  Trade  Union  Function  • 

come,  therefore,  to  the  paradox  that  the  Doctrine  of  a  Living 
Wage,  which  has  profoundly  influenced  Trade  Union  policy 
and  public  opinion  with  regard  to  all  the  other  conditions  of 
employment,  finds  least  acceptance  with  regard  to  money 
wages.  Our  own  impression  is  that,  whilst  the  Doctrine  of 
Vested  Interests  is  hopelessly  out  of  date,  and  that  of  Supply 
and  Demand  is  every  day  losing  ground,  any  application  of 
the  Doctrine  of  a  Living  Wage  is  likely,  for  the  present,  to 
be  only  gradual  and  tentative.  In  all  that  concerns  Sanita- 
tion and  Safety  it  has  been  already  adopted,  in  principle,  by 
Parliament  and  public  opinion,  though  the  actual  securing 
to  every  wage-earner  of  a  safe  and  healthy  place  of  work, 
irrespective  alike  of  what  may  have  been  customary  in  the 
trade,  and  of  the  employer's  fluctuating  profits,  or  demand 
for  labor,  is,  owing  to  apathy  and  ignorance,  still  only  im- 
perfectly accomplished.  With  regard  to  the  proportion  of 
the  day  to  be  spent  in  toil,  public  opinion  emphatically 
accepts  the  same  doctrine  in  the  case  of  children,  and,  for  the 
most  part,  in  the  case  of  women.  The  last  ten  years  have 
seen,  moreover,  a  marked  tendency  to  apply  the  same 
principles  to  the  hours  of  men,  and  in  the  case  of  railway 
servants  the  responsibility  for  preventing  labor  in  excess  of 
what  is  consistent  with  industrial  efficiency  has  already  been 
assumed  by  the  Board  of  Trade.  In  the  matter  of  wages, 
public  opinion  is  far  more  undecided.  Under  an  organisa- 
tion of  industry  in  which  employment  is  irregular,  personal 
expenditure  is  uncontrolled,  and  surplus  value  accrues  to  the 
landlord  and  capitalist,  we  cannot  expect  to  see  the  Doctrine 
of  a  Living  Wage  adopted,  with  regard  to  money  incomes, 
by  any  but  those  unfortunate  classes  whose  wages  are 
manifestly  below  the  minimum  required  for  full  physical 
efficiency.  The  events  of  1889  anc*  1893,  and  the  subse- 
quent attention  paid  to  the  wages  of  the  lower  grades  of 
workers  under  public  bodies,  indicate  an  approach  to  the  view 
that  earnings  positively  inadequate  for  industrial  efficiency 
ought,  in  the  public  interest,  and  irrespective  of  Supply  and 
Demand,  to  be  deliberately  brought  up  to  a  proper  level. 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          595 

The  foregoing  exposition  of  the  assumptions  of  Trade 
Unionism  will  have  given  the  reader  the  necessary  clue, 
both  to  the  historical  changes  in  Trade  Union  policy  from 
generation  to  generation,  and  also  to  the  diversity  at  present 
existing  in  the  Trade  Union  world.  As  soon  as  it  is  realised 
that  Trade  Unionists  are  inspired,  not  by  any  single  doctrine 
as  to  the  common  weal,  but  more  or  less  by  three  divergent 
and  even  contradictory  views  as  to  social  expediency,  we  no 
longer  look  to  them  for  any  one  consistent  and  uniform 
policy.  The  predominance  among  any  particular  section  of 
workmen,  or  at  any  particular  period,  of  one  or  other  of  the 
three  assumptions  which  we  have  described — the  Doctrine  of 
Vested  Interests,  the  Doctrine  of  Supply  and  Demand,  and 
the  Doctrine  of  a  Living  Wage — manifests  itself  in  the 
degree  of  favor  shown  to  particular  Trade  Union  Regula- 
tions. The  general  faith  in  the  Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests 
explains  why  we  find  Trade  Unionism,  in  one  industry,  or 
at  one  period,  expressing  itself  in  legally  enforced  terms  of 
apprenticeship,  customary  rates  of  wages,  the  prohibition  of 
new  processes,  strict  maintenance  of  the  lines  of  demarca- 
tion between  trades,  the  exclusion  of  "  illegal  men,"  and  the 
enforcement  of  "  patrimony  "  and  entrance  fees.  With  the 
acceptance  of  the  Doctrine  of  Supply  and  Demand  we  see 
coming  in  the  policy  of  inclusion  and  its  virtually  compulsory 
Trade  Unionism,  Sliding  Scales,  the  encouragement  of  im- 
provements in  machinery  and  the  actual  penalising  of  back- 
ward employers,  the  desire  for  a  deliberate  Regulation  of 
Output  and  the  establishment  of  alliances  with  employers 
against  the  consumer.  Finally,  in  so  far  as  the  Doctrine 
of  a  Living  Wage  obtains,  we  see  a  new  attention  to  the 
enforcement  of  Sanitation  and  Safety,  general  movements 
for  the  reduction  of  hours,  attempts  by  the  skilled  trades  to 
organise  the  unskilled  laborers  and  women  workers,  denuncia- 
tion of  Sliding  Scales  and  fluctuating  incomes,  the  abandon- 
ment of  apprenticeship  in  favor  of  universal  education,  and 
the  insistence  on  a  "  Moral  Minimum  "  wage  below  which  no 
worker  should  be  employed.  Above  all,  these  successive 


596  Trade  Union  Function 

changes  of  faith  explain  the  revolutions  which  have  taken 
place  in  Trade  Union  opinion  as  to  the  relation  of  Labor 
to  the  State.  When  men  believe  in  the  Doctrine  of  Vested 
Interests,  it  is  to  the  common  law  of  the  realm  that  they 
look  for  the  protection  of  their  rights  and  possessions.  The 
law  alone  can  secure  to  the  individual,  whether  with  regard 
to  his  right  to  a  trade  or  his  right  to  an  office,  his  privilege 
in  a  new  process  or  his  title  to  property,  the  fulfilment  of 
his  "established  expectation."  Hence  it  is  that  we  find 
eighteenth -century  Trade  Unionism  confidently  taking  for 
granted  that  all  its  regulations  ought  properly  to  be  enforced 
by  the  magistrate,  and  devoting  a  large  part  of  its  funds 
to  political  agitations  and  legal  proceedings.  When  the 
Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests  was  replaced  by  that  of  Supply 
and  Demand,  the  Trade  Unionists  naturally  turned  to  Col- 
lective Bargaining  as  their  principal  method  of  action. 
Instead  of  going  to  the  State  for  protection,  they  fiercely 
resented  any  attempt  to  interfere  with  their  struggle  with 
employers,  on  the  issue  of  which,  they  were  told,  their  wages 
must  depend.  The  Common  Law,  once  their  friend,  now 
seemed  always  their  most  dangerous  enemy,  as  it  hampered 
their  freedom  of  combination,  and  by  its  definitions  of  libel 
and  conspiracy,  set  arbitrary  limits  to  their  capacity  of  making 
themselves  unpleasant  to  the  employers  or  the  non-unionists. 
Hence  the  desire  of  the  Trade  Unionists  of  the  middle  of 
this  century,  whilst  sweeping  away  all  laws  against  combina- 
tions, to  keep  Trade  Unionism  itself  absolutely  out  of  the 
reach  of  the  law-courts.  The  growth  of  the  Doctrine  of  a 
Living  Wage,  resting  as  this  does  on  the  assumption  that 
the  conditions  of  employment  require  to  be  deliberately 
fixed,  naturally  puts  the  State  in  the  position  of  arbitrator 
between  the  workman  who  claims  more,  and  the  employer 
who  offers  less,  than  is  consistent  with  the  welfare  of  other 
sections.  But  the  appeal  is  not  to  the  Common  Law.  It 
is  no  longer  a  question  of  protecting  each  individual  in  the 
enjoyment  of  whatever  could  be  proved  to  be  his  customary 
privileges,  or  to  flow  from  identical  "  natural  rights,"  but  of 


The  Ass^^,mptions  of  Trade  Unionism          597 

prescribing,  for  the  several  sections,  the  conditions  required, 
in  the  interest  of  the  whole  community,  by  their  diverse 
actual  needs.  We  therefore  see  the  Common  Rules  for  each 
trade  embodied  in  particular  statutes,  which  the  Trade 
Unionists,  far  from  resisting,  use  their  money  and  political 
influence  to  obtain.  The  double  change  of  doctrine  has 
thus  brought  about  a  return  to  the  attitude  of  the  Old 
Unionists  of  the  eighteenth  century,  but  with  a  significant 
difference.  To-day  it  is  not  custom  or  privilege  which 
appeals  to  the  State,  but  the  requirements  of  efficient  citizen- 
ship. Whenever  a  Trade  Union  honestly  accepts  as  the 
sole  and  conclusive  test  of  any  of  its  aspirations  what  we 
have  termed  the  Doctrine  of  a  Living  Wage,  and  believes 
that  Parliament  takes  the  same  view,  we  always  find  it, 
sooner  or  later,  attempting  to  embody  that  aspiration  in  the 
statute  law. 

The  political  student  will  notice  that  there  exists  in  the 
Trade  Union  world  much  the  same  cleavage  of  opinion,  upon 
what  is  socially  expedient,  as  among  other  classes  of  society. 
All  Trade  Unionists  believe  that  the  abandonment  of  the 
conditions  of  employment  to  the  chances  of  Individual  Bar- 
gaining is  disastrous,  alike  to  the  wage-earners  and  to  the 
community.  But  when,  in  pursuance  of  this  assumption, 
they  take  concerted  action  for  the  improvement  of  their  con- 
dition, we  see  at  once  emerge  among  them  three  distinct 
schools  of  thought.  In  the  special  issues  and  technical  con- 
troversies of  Trade  Unionism  we  may  trace  the  same  broad 
generalisations,  as  to  what  organisation  of  society  is  finally 
desirable,  as  lead,  in  the  larger  world  of  politics,  to  the 
ultimate  cleavage  between  Conservatives,  Individualists,  and 
Collectivists.  The  reader  will  have  seen  that  there  is,  among 
Trade  Unionists,  a  great  deal  of  what  cannot  be  described 
otherwise  than  as  Conservatism.  The  abiding  faith  in  the 
sanctity  of  vested  interests  ;  the  strong  presumption  in  favor 
of  the  status  quo ;  the  distrust  of  innovation  ;  the  liking  for 
distinct  social  classes,  marked  off  from  each  other  by  cor- 
porate privileges  and  peculiar  traditions  ;  the  disgust  at  the 


598  Trade  Union  Function 

modern  spirit  of  self-seeking  assertiveness  ;  and  the  deep- 
rooted  conviction  that  the  only  stable  organisation  of  society 
is  that  based  on  each  man  being  secured  and  contented  in 
his  inherited  station  of  life — all  these  are  characteristic  of 
the  genuine  Conservative,  whether  in  the  Trade  Union  or 
the  State.  In  sharp  contrast  with  this  character,  and,  as 
we  think,  less  congenial  to  the  natural  bent  of  the  English 
workman,  we  have,  in  the  great  modern  unions,  a  full  measure 
of  Radical  Individualism.  The  conception  of  society  as  a 
struggle  between  warring  interests  ;  the  feeling  that  every 
man  and  every  class  is  entitled  to  all  that  they  can  get,  and 
to  nothing  more  ;  the  assumption  that  success  in  the  fight  is 
an  adequate  test  of  merit,  and,  indeed,  the  only  one  possible  ; 
and  the  bounding  optimism  which  can  confidently  place  the 
welfare  of  the  community  under  the  guardianship  of  self- 
interest — these  are  typical  of  the  "  Manchester  School,"  alike 
in  politics  and  in  Trade  Unionism.  But  in  Trade  Unionism, 
as  in  the  larger  sphere  of  politics,  the  facts  of  modern  industry 
have  led  to  a  reaction.  As  against  the  Conservative,  the 
Individualist  Radical  asserted  that  "  all  men  are  born  free  and 
equal,  with  equal  rights  to  life,  liberty,  and  the  pursuit  of 
happiness."  But  it  is  now  obvious  that  men  are  not  born 
equal,  either  in  capacity  or  in  opportunity.  There  has 
accordingly  arisen,  in  the  Trade  Union  as  in  the  political 
world,  a  school  of  thought  which  asserts  that  a  free  struggle 
among  unequal  individuals,  or  combinations  of  individuals, 
means  the  permanent  oppression  and  degradation  of  those 
who  start  handicapped,  and  inevitably  results  in  a  tacit  con- 
spiracy among  the  more  favored  classes  to  maintain  or 
improve  their  own  positions  of  vantage  at  the  cost  of  the 
community  at  large.  The  Collectivist  accordingly  insists  on 
the  need  for  a  conscious  and  deliberate  organisation  of  society, 
based,  not  on  vested  interests  or  the  chances  of  the  fight,  but 
on  the  scientifically  ascertained  needs  of  each  section  of 
citizens.  Thus,  within  the  Trade  Union  movement,  we  find 
the  Collectivist-minded  working-man  grounding  his  regula- 
tion of  the  conditions  of  employment  upon  what  we  have 


The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism          599 

called  the  Doctrine  of  a  Living  Wage.  In  the  wider  world 
of  politics  we  see  the  Collectivist  statesman  groping  his  way 
to  the  similar  conception  of  a  deliberate  organisation  of  pro- 
duction, regulation  of  service,  and  apportionment  of  income — 
in  a  word,  to  such  a  conscious  adjustment  of  the  resources 
of  the  community  to  its  needs  as  will  result  in  its  highest 
possible  efficiency.  In  the  Trade  Union  world  the  rival 
assumptions  exist  side  by  side,  and  the  actual  regulation  of 
industry  is  a  perpetually  shifting  compromise  between  them. 
The  political  student  may  infer  that,  in  the  larger  organisa- 
tion of  society,  the  rival  conceptions  of  Conservatism,  Indi- 
vidualism, and  Collectivism  will  long  co-exist.  Any  further 
application  of  Collectivism,  whether  in  the  Trade  Union  or 
the  political  world,  depends,  it  is  clear,  on  an  increase  in  our 
scientific  knowledge,  no  less  than  on  the  growth  of  new 
habits  of  deliberate  social  co-operation.  Progress  in  this 
direction  must,  therefore,  be  gradual,  and  will  probably  be 
slow.  And  the  philosophical  Collectivist  will,  we  think,  fore- 
see that,  whether  in  the  regulation  of  labor,  the  incidence  of 
taxation,  or  the  administration  of  public  services,  any  stable 
adjustment  of  social  resources  to  social  needs  must  always 
take  into  account,  not  only  the  scientifically  ascertained  con- 
ditions of  efficiency,  but  also  the  "  established  expectation  " 
and  the  "  fighting  force  "  of  all  the  classes  concerned. 


PART  III 
TRADE    UNION    THEORY 


CHAPTER    I 

THE   VERDICT   OF   THE    ECONOMISTS 

DOWN  to  within  the  last  thirty  years  it  would  have  been 
taken  for  granted,  by  every  educated  man,  that  Trade 
Unionism,  as  a  means  of  bettering  the  condition  of  the  work- 
man, was  "  against  Political  Economy." x  This  impression 
was  derived,  not  so  much  from  any  explicit  declaration  of 
the  economists,  as  from  the  general  view  of  wages  which 
enlightened  public  opinion  had  accepted  from  them.  The 
Theory  of  the  Wage  Fund,  in  conjunction  with  closely 
related  theories  of  the  accumulation  of  capital  and  the 
increase  of  population,  seemed  definitely  to  contradict  the 
fundamental  assumptions  on  which  Trade  Unionism  de- 
pended. If  Political  Economy  was  understood  to  demon- 
strate it  was  plainly  impossible,  in  any  given  state 
of  capital  and  population,  to  bring  about  any  genuine 
and  permanent  rise  of  wages,  otherwise  than  in  the  slow 
course  of  generations,  it  was  clearly  not  worth  while 
troubling  about  the  pretensions  of  workmen  ignorant  of 
economic  science.  Accordingly,  for  the  first  three  quarters 
of  the  century  we  find,  beyond  the  accustomed  denunciation 
of  outrages  and  strikes,  practically  nothing  but  a  general 
and  undiscriminating  hostility  to  Trade  Unionism  in  the 

1  Even  the  Christian  Socialists,  the  Positivists,  and  the  champions  of  labor 
in  Parliament  usually  regarded  the  pretensions  of  Trade  Unionism  as  being  in 
contradiction  to  the  orthodox  Political  Economy,  in  which  they  accordingly  did 
not  believe  ! 


604  Trade  Union  Theory 

abstract,  couched  in  the  language  of  theoretical  economics. 
And  although  the  theory,  with  all  its  corollaries,  has  now 
been  abandoned  by  economic  authority,  it  still  lingers  in  the 
public  mind,  and  lies  at  the  root  of  most  of  the  current 
middle-class  objections  to  Trade  Unionism.  We  must  there- 
fore clear  the  ground  of  this  obsolete  criticism  before  we 
can  proceed  to  estimate  Trade  Union  pretensions  in  the 
light  of  the  economic  science  of  to-day. 

We  need  not  here  enter  into  any  detailed  history  or 
elaborate  analysis  of  the  celebrated  Theory  of  the  Wage 
Fund.1  As  widely  popularised  by  J.  R.  M'Culloch,  from 
1823  onward,  this  theory  declared  that  "  wages  depend  at 
any  particular  moment  on  the  magnitude  of  the  Fund  or 
Capital  appropriated  to  the  payment  of  wages  compared  with 
the  number  of  laborers.  .  .  .  Laborers  are  everywhere  the 
divisor,  capital  the  dividend." 2  Nor  was  this  statement 
confined  to  the  truism  that  the  average  wages  of  the  wage- 
receiving  class  was  to  be  found  by  dividing  the  aggregate 

1  The  most  recent,  and  in  many  respects  the  best,  account  of  this  celebrated 
theory  is  to  be  found  in  Wages  and  Capital :  an  Examination  of  the  Wages  Fiind 
Doctrine  (London,  1896),  by  F.  W.  Taussig,  Professor  of  Political   Economyjn 
Harvard  University.     A  Histoiy  of  the   Theories  of  Production  and  Distribution 
in  English  Political  Economy  from  IJj6  to  184.8,  by  Edwin  Cannan  (London, 
1893),  contains  an  acutely  critical  analysis.     The  fullest  exposition  of  the  modem 
economic  view  is,  perhaps,  The  Wages  Question :  a   Treatise  on  Wages  and  the 
Wages  Class  (New  York,   1876;    London,   1891),   by  F.  A.   Walker.     In  the 
Principles  of  Economics  (Book  VI.  ch.   ii.   page   618  of  3rd   edition,   London, 
1895)  Professor  Marshall  explains  in  a  long  note  what  Ricardo  and  Mill  really 
meant  by  their  statements  on  the  wage-fund. 

2  Article  on   "Wages"  in    Encyclop&dia  Britannica    (4th   edition,    1823), 
republished  with  additions  as  A  Treatise  on  the  Circumstances  which  determine  the 
Rate  of  Wages  and  the  Condition  of  the  Labouring  Classes  (London,  1851).     A 
widely  read  American  follower  of  Ricardo  and  M'Culloch  put  the  case  as  follows  : 
"  That   which  pays  for  labor  in  every  country  is  a   certain  portion  of  actually 
accumulated  capital,  which  cannot  be  increased  by  the  proposed  action  of  Govern- 
ment,  nor  by  the  influence  of  public   opinion,  nor  by  combinations  among  the 
workmen   themselves.      There  is  also   in  every  country  a   certain  number  of 
laborers,  and  this  number  cannot  be  diminished  by  the  proposed  action  of  Govern- 
ment, nor  by  public  opinion,  nor  by  combinations  among  themselves.     There  is 
to  be  a  division  now  among  all  these  laborers  of  the  portion  of  capital  actually 
there  present "    {Elements  of  Political  Economy \  by  A.   L.    Perry,   New  York, 
1866,  p.  122).     We  understand  that  this  work  has  run  through  about   twenty 
editions,  and  is  still  a  popular  text-book  in  the  United  States.      An  edition  was 
published  in  London  in  1891. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  605 

"  fund  devoted  to  their  payment "  by  the  number  of  the 
laborers  for  the  time  being.  What  was  insisted  on  was  that 
the  amount  of  this  "  fund "  was  necessarily  predetermined 
by  the  economic  circumstances  of  the  community  at  any 
given  time.  The  amount  of  the  "  capital  "  depended  on  the 
extent  of  the  savings  from  the  product  of  the  past.  The 
extent  of  the  fund  to  be  appropriated  to  the  payment  of 
wages  depended  on  how  much  of  that  capital  was  required 
for  plant  and  materials.  Hence  the  amount  of  the  Wage 
Fund  at  any  particular  moment  was  absolutely  predetermined, 
partly  by  the  action  of  the  community  in  the  past,  and,  as 
suggested  by  Cairnes,  partly  by  the  technical  character  of  the 
industries  of  the  present.1  "  There  is  supposed  to  be,"  wrote 
J.  S.  Mill,  "at  any  given  instant  a  sum  of  wealth  which  is 
unconditionally  devoted  to  the  payment  of  wages  of  labor. 
This  sum  is  not  regarded  as  unalterable,  for  it  is  augmented 
by  saving  and  increases  with  the  progress  of  society ;  but  it 
is  reasoned  upon  as  at  any  given  moment  a  predetermined 
amount.  More  than  that  amount  it  is  assumed  that  the 
wage-receiving  class  cannot  possibly  divide  among  them  ; 
that  amount  and  no  less  they  cannot  but  obtain.  So  that 
the  sum  to  be  divided  being  fixed  the  wages  of  each  depend 
solely  on  the  divisor,  the  number  of  participants." 2  It 
was  a  plain  inference  from  this  view  that,  whatever  might 
automatically  occur  in  the  future  if  one  factor  increased 
faster  than  the  other,  the  terms  of  the  current  bargain  for 

1  Some  Leading  Principles  of  Political  Economy  newly  expounded  (London, 
1874),  pp.  199-200. 

2  Mill's  review  of  W.  T.  Thornton's  book  On  Labour,  in  Fortnightly  Review, 
May   1869;    reprinted  in  Dissertations   and   Discussions  (London,    1875),  vo^ 
iv.  p.  43. 

This  conception  of  a  definitely  limited  wage-fund,  all  in  hand  at  the 
beginning  of  the  year,  and  all  replaced  at  its  close,  seems  to  have  been  derived 
from  the  case  of  the  English  wheat -growing  farmer,  who  was  supposed  to 
calculate,  when  he  had  reaped  his  harvest,  how  much  he  could  lay  out  in  wages 
until  the  next  harvest  was  gathered  in.  A  closer  analogy  would  have  been  the 
practice  of  English  Government  Departments,  such  as  the  Admiralty  Shipbuilding 
yards,  which  have  allotted  to  them,  at  the  beginning  of  each  financial  year, 
definite  sums,  theoretically  insusceptible  of  increase,  to  be  expended  in  wages 
during  the  year. 


606  Trade  Union  Theory 

the  hire  of  labor  at  any  particular  moment  were,  as  regards 
the  wage-earning  class  as  a  whole,  absolutely  unalterable, 
whether  by  law  or  by  negotiation.  "There  is  no  use,"  the 
workmen  were  told,  "  in  arguing  against  any  one  of  the  four 
fundamental  rules  of  arithmetic.  The  question  of  wages  is  a 
question  of  division.  It  is  complained  that  the  quotient  is 
too  small.  Well,  then,  how  many  ways  are  there  to  make  a 
quotient  larger?  Two  ways.  Enlarge  your  dividend,  the 
divisor  remaining  the  same,  and  the  quotient  will  be  larger ; 
lessen  your  divisor,  the  dividend  remaining  the  same,  and 
the  quotient  will  be  larger."1  The  wage -earners  in  the 
aggregate  were  at  any  moment  already  obtaining  all  that 
could  possibly  be  conceded  to  them  at  that  moment,  and 
any  gain  made  by  one  section  of  them  could  only  be  made 
at  the  expense  of  their  weaker  colleagues.  Conversely,  any 
reduction  suffered  by  one  section  of  the  wage-earners  was 
necessarily  and  contemporaneously  balanced  by  gain  to 
some  other  section.  "  All  the  capital,"  declared  M'Culloch, 
"  through  the  higgling  of  the  market  will  be  equitably 
distributed  among  all  the  laborers.  Hence  it  is  idle  to 
suppose  that  the  efforts  of  the  capitalists  to  cheapen  labor 
can  have  the  smallest  influence  on  its  medium  price." 2  It 
followed  with  no  less  logic  that  any  efforts  of  laborers  in 
the  opposite  direction  were  equally  futile.  Public  opinion 

1  Elements  of  Political  Economy,  by  A.  L.  Perry,  p.  1 23. 

2  Even  after  a  lifetime  of  economic  study,    M'Culloch  could   deliberately 
repeat  that  "  all  the  wealth  of  the  country  applicable  to  the  payment  of  wages  is 
uniformly,  in  all  ordinary  cases,  divided  among  the  laborers.  .  .  .  It  is  impossible 
for  the  employers  of  labor  artificially  to  reduce  the  rate  of  wages  "  (A  Treatise  on 
the  Circumstances  which  determine  the  Rate  of  Wages  and  the  Condition  of  the 
Labouring  Classes,  London,  1851,  pp.  48-49).       "A  single  rich  man  may  take 
advantage  of  a  single  poor  man  by  availing  himself  of  the  necessities  or  simplicity 
of  the  latter.      But  the  body  of  capitalists  in  any  country  will  always  pay  away  in 
wages  to  the  body  of  working  men  all  the  funds  which  they  have  applicable  to 
the  employment  of  labor"  {An  Essay  on  the  Relations  of  Labour  and  Capital, 
London,    1854,   by  C.    Morrison,   p.    18).      Fawcett   apparently   retained   the 
same  view  down  to  his  death.      "The  capital  of  the  country  provides  its  wage- 
fund.     This  wage-fund  is  distributed  amongst  the  whole  wage-receiving  popula- 
tion, and  therefore  the  average  of  each  individual's  wages  cannot  increase  unless 
either  the  number  of  those  who  receive  wages  is  diminished,  or  the  wage-fund  is 
augmented." — Manual  of  Political  Economy,  by  Henry  Fawcett  (London,  1869), 
pp.  206-207  ;  Lift,  by  Leslie  Stephen  (London,  1886),  p.  157. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  607 

accordingly  unhesitatingly  refuted  Trade  Unionism,  to  use 
the  words  of  one  of  the  most  eminent  of  modern  economists, 
"  with  a  summary  reference  to  the  doctrine  of  the  wage-fund. 
Strikes  could  not  increase  the  wage -fund,  therefore  they 
could  not  enhance  wages.  If  they  should  appear  to  raise  the 
rate  in  any  trade,  this  must  be  due  either  to  a  corresponding 
loss  in  the  regularity  of  employment  or  to  an  equivalent  loss, 
in  regularity  or  in  rate,  by  some  other  trade  or  trades 
occupying  a  position  of  economical  disadvantage.  Hence 
strikes  could  not  benefit  the  wages  class." l  But  the 
theory  went  much  further  than  the  mere  negativing  of 
strikes  and  combinations.  It  left  no  room  for  any  elevation 
of  the  wage-earners  even  if  the  improvement  justified  itself 
by  an  increase  in  productive  capacity.  If  one  section  of  the 
wage-earners  succeeded,  by  peaceful  negotiation  or  Jaw,  in  so 
bettering  their  own  conditions  of  employment  as  positively 
to  increase  their  productive  efficiency,  this  would  still  bring 
no  greater  reward  to  the  class  as  a  whole.  Though  the 
increase  in  the  cost  of  their  labor  might  soon  be  made  up  to 
their  employers  by  its  greater  product,  yet  this  increased 
drain  on  the  wage-fund  must  automatically  have  depressed 
the  condition,  and  so  lowered  the  efficiency  of  other  sections, 
with  the  result  that,  though  the  inequality  between  the 
sections  would  have  increased,  the  aggregate  efficiency  of  the 
wage-earners  as  a  whole  would  not  have  risen.  Thus  every 
factory  act,  which  increased  the  immediate  cost  of  woman  or 
child  labor,  had  to  be  paid  for  by  a  contemporaneous 
decrease  in  somebody's  wages ;  and  every  time  a  new 
expense  for  sanitation  or  precautions  against  accidents  was 
imposed  on  the  capitalists,  some  of  the  wage-earners  had 
automatically  to  suffer  a  diminution  of  income.2 

1  The  Wages  Question,  by  F.  A.  Walker,  p.  387.     M'Culloch  had  expressly 
observed   in   his   article  on  "  Combinations "  in  the  Encyclopedia   Britannica 
(1823)  that  "nothing  but  the  merest  ignorance  could  make  it  supposed  that 
wages  could  really  be  increased   by  such  proceedings.     They  depend  on  the 
principle  which    they  cannot  affect,  that  is  on  the  proportion  between  capital 
and  population ;  and  cannot  be  increased  except  by  the  increase  of  the  former 
as  compared  with  the  latter." 

2  It  followed  logically  that  bad    legislation  could   not   depress,    and   good 


608  Trade  Union  Theory 

Though  public  opinion  accepted  the  statical  view  of  the 
wage -fund  as  conclusive  against  the  possibility  of  any 
general  alteration  of  the  terms  of  the  labor  contract,  this 
crude  conception  supplied  no  answer  to  the  assertion  that 
the  workmen  in  any  particular  trade  might  need  to  defend 
their  own  wages  against  special  encroachment,  or  that  they 
might  find  it  possible,  if  only  at  the  expense  of  other  sections 
of  wage-earners,  to  exact  better  conditions  for  themselves. 
But  here  the  Trade  Unionists  found  themselves  confronted 
with  the  economic  "  laws "  determining  the  employment  of 
capital.  "  If,"  observed  M'Culloch,  "  the  wages  paid  to  the 
laborers  engaged  in  any  particular  employment  be  improperly 
reduced,  the  capitalists  who  carry  it  on  will  obviously  gain 
the  whole  amount  of  this  reduction  over  and  above  the  common 
and  ordinary  rate  of  profit  obtained  by  the  capitalists  engaged 

legislation  could  not  raise,  the  condition  of  the  wage-earners.  M'Culloch  and 
Harriet  Martineau  went  this  length  with  regard  to  Combination  Laws  and 
Factory  Acts  respectively.-  "  Looking  generally  to  the  whole  of  the  employments 
carried  on  in  the  country,"  wrote  the  former  in  1823,  and  again  in  1851,  "we 
do  not  believe  that  the  Combination  Laws  had  any  sensible  influence  on  the 
average  and  usual  rate  of  wages.  That  they  occasionally  kept  wages  at  a  lower 
rate  in  some  very  confined  businesses  than  they  would  otherwise  have  sunk  to 
may  be  true,  though  for  that  very  reason  they  must  have  equally  elevated  them 
in  others"  (article  on  "Combinations"  in  Encyclopedia  Britannica,  4th  edition, 
1823 ;  Treatise  on  the  Circumstances  -which  determine  the  Rate  of  Wages, 
London,  1851,  p.  80).  In  1833  Harriet  Martineau  wrote:  "Mrs.  Marcet  is 
sorry  to  find  that  Mr.  E.  R[omilly]  and  I  are  of  the  same  opinion  about  the 
Factory  Bill,  and  I  am  very  glad.  She  ought  to  hold  the  same,  namely  that 
legislation  cannot  interfere  effectually  between  parents  and  children  in  the  present 
state  of  the  labor-market.  Our  operations  must  be  directed  towards  proportioning 
the  labor  and  capital,  and  not  upon  restricting  the  exchange  of  the  one  for  the 
other ;  an  exchange  which  must  be  voluntary,  whatever  the  law  may  say  about  it. 
We  cannot  make  parents  give  their  children  a  half-holiday  every  day  in  the  year, 
unless  we  also  give  compensation  for  the  loss  of  the  children's  labor.  The  case 
of  those  wretched  factory  children  seems  desperate  ;  the  only  hope  seems  to  be 
that  the  race  will  die  out  in  two  or  three  generations,  by  which  time  machinery 
may  be  found  to  do  their  work  better  than  their  miserable  selves.  Every  one's 
countenance  falls  at  the  very  mention  of  the  evidence  which  has  lately  appeared 
in  the  papers  "  (Harriet  Martineads  Autobiography ',  by  Maria  Weston  Chapman, 
London,  1877,  vol.  iii.  p.  87).  It  is  only  fair  to  add  that  Harriet  Martineau, 
unlike  M'Culloch,  was  converted  by  a  wider  knowledge  of  the  facts  of 
industrial  life.  She  herself  records  how  what  she  saw  in  America  brought  her, 
not  only  to  appreciate  the  value  of  Robert  Owen's  ideas  and  to  retract  her  former 
economic  dogmatism,  but  also  to  believe  that  the  future  possibly  lay  with  a 
Collectivist  organisation  of  society. — Ibid.  vol.  i.  p.  232, 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  609 

in  other  businesses.  But  a  discrepancy  of  this  kind  could  not 
possibly  continue.  Additional  capital  would  immediately 
begin  to  be  attracted  to  the  department  where  wages  are  low 
and  profits  high,  and  its  owners  would  be  obliged,  in  order  to 
obtain  laborers,  to  offer  them  higher  wages.  It  is  clear, 
therefore,  that  if  wages  be  unduly  reduced  in  any  branch  of 
industry,  they  will  be  raised  to  their  proper  level,  without 
any  effort  on  the  part  of  the  workmen,  by  the  competition  of 
capitalists."1  Similarly,  if  the  laborers  insisted  on  better 
terms  in  a  particular  trade,  this  must  reduce  its  profitableness 
to  the  employers.  And  capital  being  assumed  to  be  both 
mobile  and  omniscient,  it  at  once  began  to  "  flow "  out  of 
this  less  profitable  industry,  in  order  to  "  flow "  in  to  the 
other  trades  in  which  the  cost  of  labor  would  simultaneously 
and  automatically  have  been  reduced.  The  laborers  who 
had  raised  their  conditions  above  the  "  proper "  level  found 
themselves  therefore  between  the  horns  of  a  dilemma.  If  they 
all  wished  to  be  employed  at  their  trade,  wages  must  go  back 
to  the  old  level,  and  (seeing  that  part  of  the  previous  wage- 
fund  had  been  diverted  away)  even  temporarily  below  it.  If, 
on  the  other  hand,  they  insisted  on  preserving  their  newly- 
won  better  conditions,  it  was  obvious  that  only  a  smaller 
number  of  them  could  find  employment,  the  more  so 
as  the  portion  of  the  wage -fund  invested  in  that  trade 
would  positively  have  diminished.  The  displaced  workmen, 
as  it  was  often  explained  to  them,  would  thus  have  killed  the 
goose  which  laid  the  golden  eggs.  The  few  who  continued 
to  find  full  employment  at  their  trade  might  have  gained, 
but  taking  the  trade  as  a  whole,  the  men  would  clearly  have 
lost  by  the  transaction.2  "  And  hence  the  fundamental  prin- 
ciple, that  there  are  no  means  by  which  wages  can  be  raised, 

1  Article  on  "Combinations,"  by  J.  R.  M'Culloch,  vc\  Encyclopedia  Britannica, 
4th  edition  (Edinburgh,  1823),  repeated  in  his  Treatise  of  1851. 

2  If  the  attempt  to  get  the  better  conditions  were  made  by  means  of  Mutual 
Insurance  or  Collective  Bargaining — as  the  economists  always  assumed  would  be 
the  case — it  would  therefore  almost  certainly   fail,  as   the    displaced  workmen 
would,  sooner  or  later,  be  driven  to  compete  for  employment  with  those  who 
succeeded  in  getting  work,  with  the  result  that  things  would  revert  to  the  old 
level. 

VOL.  II  2  R 


610  Trade  Union  Theory 

other  than  by  accelerating  the  increase  of  capital  as  compared 
with  population,  or  by  retarding  the  increase  of  population 
as  compared  with  capital,  and  every  scheme  for  raising 
wages  which  is  not  bottomed  on  this  principle,  or  which  has 
not  an  increase  of  the  ratio  of  capital  to  population  for  its 
object,  must  be  completely  nugatory  and  ineffectual." l 

And  when  the  Trade  Unionists  turned  from  the  question 
of  wages  to-day,  to  the  possibility  of  raising  them  in  the 
following  year,  middle-class  opinion  had  a  no  less  conclusive 
answer  to  their  claim.  The  future  wage-fund  that  would  be 
applicable  for  the  payment  of  laborers  in  the  ensuing  year 
was,  of  course,  necessarily  limited  by  the  available  posses- 
sions of  the  community.  But  within  that  limit  its  amount 
depended  on  the  will  of  the  owners.  They  might,  if  they 
chose,  consume  any  part  of  it  for  their  own  enjoyment,  or 
they  might  be  tempted  to  abstain  from  this  consumption, 
and  employ  a  larger  or  smaller  proportion  of  their  total 
possessions  in  productive  industry.  Ricardo  had  incidentally 
observed  that  the  "  motive  for  accumulation  will  diminish 
with  every  diminution  of  profit,"  2  and  it  was  assumed  without 
hesitation  that,  whatever  might  be  the  various  motives  for 
saving,  these  motives  would  be  stimulated  or  depressed 
according  to  the  rate  of  interest  which  might  be  expected  to 
be  gained  from  the  capital  so  invested.  "  The  higher  the 
rate  of  profit  in  any  community,  the  greater  will  be  the  pro- 
portion of  the  annual  savings  which  is  added  to  capital,  and 
the  greater  will  be  the  inducement  to  save."3  It  thus 
followed  that  the  rate  at  which  capital,  and  therefore  the 
wage -fund,  would  be  increased  would  vary  according  to 
profit,  rising  when  the  rate  of  profit  rose,  and  falling  when 
the  rate  of  profit  fell.  "  The  greater  the  proportion  of 

1  Article  on  "Wages,"  by  J.  R.  M'Culloch,  in  Encyclopedia  Britannica,  4th 
edition  (Edinburgh,  1823) ;  see  his  Principles  of  Political  Economy  (Edinburgh, 
1825),  part  iii.  sec.  7. 

2  On  the  Principles   of  Political  Economy  and  Taxation   (London,    1817), 
p.  136. 

3  Article    on   the  effects  of  machinery  in  the   Westminster  Review,  January 
1826,   by  W.    Ellis,   quoted  by  J.    S.   Mill  (Principles  of  Political  Economy, 
Book  IV.  chap.  iv.  p.  441  of  1865  edition). 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  611 

wages  to  profits  the  smaller  the  tendency  to  national 
accumulation."  l  Any  rise  of  wages  could,  therefore,  only 
be  temporary,  and  must  quickly  counteract  itself,  for  "an 
increase  in  wages  reduces  the  profits,  and  reduces  the  induce- 
ment to  save  and  extend  business,  and  this  again  tends  to  a 
reduction  of  wages." 2  Cairnes,  in  an  unguarded  moment, 
went  even  further.  "  Profits,"  he  said,  "  are  already  at  or 
within  a  hand's  breadth  of  the  minimum  .  .  .  below  which, 
if  the  return  on  capital  fall,  accumulation,  at  least  for  the 
purpose  of  investment,  will  cease  for  want  of  adequate 
inducement." 3  This  automatic  check  on  the  wage-earners' 
pretensions  applies,  it  is  clear,  to  more  than  the  money 
wages.  If  by  means  of  a  Factory  Act  they  had  secured  for 
the  future  shorter  hours  or  better  sanitation,  this  prospect  of 
a  reduction  of  profits  would  instantly  limit  the  capitalists' 
desire  to  accumulate,  and  would  induce  them  as  a  class  to 
spend  more  of  their  incomes  on  personal  enjoyment.  "  There 
is  only  a  certain  produce,"  wrote  one  widely-read  critic  of 
Trade  Unionism,  "  to  be  divided  between  capitalist  and 
laborer.  If  more  be  given  to  the  laborer  than  nature  awards, 
a  smaller  amount  will  remain  for  the  capitalist ;  the  spirit  of 
accumulation  will  be  checked  ;  less  will  be  devoted  to  pro- 
ductive purposes  ;  the  wage-fund  will  dwindle,  and  the  wage 
of  the  laborer  will  inevitably  fall.  For  a  time,  indeed,  a 
natural  influence  may  be  dammed  back  ;  but  only  to  act, 
ultimately,  with  accumulated  force.  In  the  long  run,  God's 
laws  will  overwhelm  all  human  obstructions."4  On  the 

1  Trade  Unionism,  by  James  Stirling,  p.  29. 

2  T.  S.  Cree,  A  Criticism  of  the  Theory  of  Trades  Unions  (Glasgow,  1 89 1 ),  p.  25. 

3  Some  Leading  Principles  of  Political  Economy  newly  expounded,  by  J.  E. 
Cairnes  (London,   1874),   pp.    256-258.      This  unlucky  prophecy   was    written 
in  that  year  of  colossal  business  profits,  1873  !     At  that  date  the  yield  on  good 
"trustee  "  securities  in  England  was  about  £4  per  ;£ioo.     It  has  since  fallen 
(1897)  by  no  less  than  25  per  cent,  yet  accumulation  and  investment  have  gone 
on  faster  than  ever. 

4  Trade  Unionism,  with  Remarks  on  the  Report  of  the  Commissioners  on 
Trades  Unions,  by  James  Stirling  (Glasgow,    1869),   2nd   edition,    1869;    new 
edition,    1889,   pp.   26-27.      This   sapient  work  was  translated  into  French  by 
T.  N.  Bernard,  and  published  as  L?  Unionisms  des  Ouvriers  en  Angleterre.     See 
also  the  article  by  the  same  author  in  Recess  Studies  (Edinburgh,  1870). 


6 1 2  Trade  Union  Theory 

other  hand,  if  wages  remained  low,  and  the  rate  of  profit 
high,  the  capitalists  would  as  a  class  be  tempted  to  limit 
their  personal  expenditure,  in  order  to  take  advantage  of  the 
high  profits  by  accumulating  as  much  capital  as  possible. 
Thus,  as  a  recent  opponent  of  Trade  Unionism  quite 
logically  explained,  the  laborer's  "  policy  should  be  to  make 
the  position  of  employers  as  pleasant  and  profitable  as 
possible,  and  to  coax  them  into  trade,  just  as  a  shopkeeper 
tries  to  entice  customers  into  his  shop."  *  If  wages  relatively 
to  profits  were  low  one  year,  they  would  tend  automatically 
to  rise  next  year  ;  if  they  were  high  one  year,  they  would 
automatically  be  depressed  in  the  following  year.2 

This  theory  of  the  rate  of  accumulation  of  capital,  taken 
in  conjunction  with  the  Theory  of  the  Wage  Fund,  appeared 
finally  to  dispose  of  every  part  of  the  Trade  Union  case. 
But  enlightened  public  opinion  had  yet  another  argument  to 
adduce,  one  which  cut  at  the  root,  not  of  Trade  Unionism 
only,  but  of  all  genuine  improvement  of  the  condition  of  the 
present  generation  of  laborers,  even  if  the  capitalists  actually 
desired  to  share  their  own  profits  with  them.  This  was  the 
celebrated  "  principle  of  population."  Malthus  had  proved 

1  T.  S.  Cree,  A  Criticism  of  the  Theory  of  Trades  Unions,  p.  30. 

2  "  While  the  terms  of  a  particular  bargain  are  of  importance  to  the  individual 
workman  and  employer  concerned,  they  are  not  of  much  importance  to  the  work- 
men and  employers  as  a  whole,  as  there  is  always  a  compensating  action  going  on 
which  is  bringing  wages  to  a  true  economical  point." — Ibid.  p.  10. 

"The  price  of  labor,  at  any  given  time  and  place,  is  not  a  matter  left  to  the 
volition  of  the  contracting  parties  ;  but  is  determined  for  them  by  a  self-adjusting 
mechanism  of  natural  forces.  The  amount  of  capital  devoted  to  production — 
according  to  the  prevalent  strength  of  the  effective  desire  of  accumulation — deter- 
mines the  force  of  the  demand  for  labor  :  the  number  of  laborers  desirous  of 
employment — in  accordance  with  the  prevalent  strength  of  the  instinct  of  popula- 
tion— regulates  the  supply.  All  unknown  to  the  capitalist  and  laborer,  the  rate 
of  wages  is  fixed  for  them,  by  the  natural  adjustment  of  these  antagonist  forces  ; 
the  amount  of  labor  demanded  by  the  whole  body  of  capitalists  on  the  one  hand, 
the  amount  supplied  by  the  whole  body  of  laborers  on  the  other.  As  Mr.  Mill 
himself  has  tersely  put  it,  in  his  Political  Economy,  '  Wages  .  .  .  depend  on 
the  ratio  between  population  and  capital.'  When,  therefore,  the  capitalist  and 
the  laborer  come  to  divide  the  product  of  their  joint  industry,  they  find  the 
division  ready  made  to  their  hand.  The  profits  due  to  the  one,  and  the  wages 
due  to  the  other,  have  been  apportioned,  by  the  unerring  agency  of  natural 
influences,  and  no  room  is  left  for  cavil  or  coercion." — "  Mr.  Mill  on  Trades 
Unions,"  by  James  Stirling,  in  Recess  Studies  (Edinburgh,  1870),  p.  311. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  6 1 3 

that  human  fecundity  was,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  far  in  excess 
of  the  actual  increase  of  population,  and  that  the  numbers  of 
mankind  were  kept  down  by  the  positive  checks  of  vice  and 
misery,  notably  by  the  privations  and  hardships  suffered  by 
the  poor.  It  was  the  part  of  wisdom  to  substitute,  for  these 
positive  checks,  that  prudential  restraint  which  delayed 
marriage  or  forewent  parentage,  and  the  only  hope  for  the 
laborers  lay  in  a  great  extension  of  this  prudential  restraint, 
so  that  the  ratio  of  capital  to  wage-earners  might  increase. 
This  hope  was  at  best  a  faint  one,  because  the  prudential 
restraint  would  have  to  extend  to  the  whole  wage-earning 
class,  and  would  have  to  be  maintained  with  ever-increasing 
rigor,  as  the  resulting  fall  in  the  rate  of  profit  slackened  the 
rate  of  accumulation.  And  whatever  degree  of  prudence 
might  animate  the  wage-earning  class  at  any  particular  time, 
it  was  taken  for  granted  that  the  rate  of  increase  must 
habitually  rise  when  wages  increased,  and  fall  when  wages 
were  reduced.  "  Thus,  if  combination  were  for  a  time  to 
raise  wages,  the  growth  of  the  wage-fund  would  be  unnatur- 
ally retarded,  whilst  a  fictitious  stimulus  would  be  given  to 
population  by  the  momentary  enrichment  of  the  laboring 
class.  A  diminished  demand  for  labor  would  coincide  with 
an  increased  supply.  The  laborer's  wages  would  be  forced 
down  to  starvation-point  ;  and  his  last  state  would  be  worse 
than  his  first." *  The  ratio  of  population  to  capital  was, 
indeed,  effectively  defended  on  both  sides  from  any  but 
transitory  alteration.  If  capital  fell  behind  population,  wages 
fell,  but  this  very  fall  automatically  brought  about  a 
quickening  of  accumulation  and  a  slackening  of  the  increase 
of  population.  If  population  fell  behind  capital,  wages  rose, 
but  this  very  rise  caused  a  check  to  accumulation  and  a 
stimulus  to  the  increase  of  population.  "  Should  a  union 
succeed,"  said  the  public  opinion  of  the  last  generation,  "  in 
shutting  out  competition,  and  so  unnaturally  raising  wages 
and  lowering  profits  in  some  particular  trade,  a  twofold 
reaction  tends  to  restore  the  natural  equilibrium.  An 

1   Trade  Unionism,  by  James  Stirling,  p.  29. 


6 14  Trade  Union  Theory 

increased  population  will  add  to  the  supply  of  labor,  while 
a  diminished  wage-fund  will  lessen  the  demand  for  it.  The 
joint  action  of  these  two  principles  will — sooner  or  later — 
overcome  the  power  of  any  arbitrary  organisation,  and  restore 
profits  and  wages  to  their  natural  level."  l  "  Against  these 
barriers,"  said  Cairnes,  "  Trade  Unions  must  dash  themselves 
in  vain.  They  are  not  to  be  broken  through  or  eluded  by 
any  combinations  however  universal ;  for  they  are  the 
barriers  set  by  Nature  herself."  2 

So  firmly  were  the  various  parts  of  the  economist's  theory 
bolted  together,  that  there  was  only  one  way  in  which  it  was 
even  conceivable  that  a  Trade  Union  could  better  the  con- 
ditions of  its  members.  If  the  workmen  in  any  trade  could, 
either  by  law  or  by  an  absolutely  firm  combination  extending 
from  one  end  of  the  kingdom  to  another,  permanently  restrict 
the  numbers  entering  that  trade,  they  might,  it  was  admitted, 
gradually  force  their  employers  to  offer  them  higher  wages. 
Hence  it  was  habitually  assumed  that  the  whole  aim  and 
purpose  of  Trade  Unionism  was  to  bring  about  this  position 

1  Trade  Unionism,  by  James  Stirling,  p.  27.     "  In  a  thickly  populated  country, 
which  has  no  vent  for  its  surplus  population  abroad,  Political  Economy  has  but  one 
advice  to  give  to  the  younger  members  of  the  poorer  classes.    The  postponement  of, 
or  abstinence  from,  marriage,  ox  from  giving  birth  to  children,  to  a  veiy  great  extent,  is 
in  such  a  case  the  only  available  preventive  against  the  evils  of  too  rapid  an  increase 
of  numbers." — C.  Morrison,  The  Relations  between  Labour  and  Capital,  p.  51. 

2  Some  Leading  Principles  of  Political  Economy  newly  expounded,  by  J.  E. 
Cairnes  (London,    1874),   p.    338.      In  contrast  with  the   methods  of  abstract 
reasoning,  without  inquiry  into  the  facts  of  industry,  which  were  pursued  by  the 
economists  of  the  time,  may  be  mentioned  the  interesting  descriptions  of   the 
economic  circumstances   of  the  Sheffield  trades   published  by  Dr.    G.    Calvert 
Holland.    In  his  Mortality,  Sufferings,  and  Diseases  of  Grinders,  part  ii.  (Sheffield, 
1842),  he  gives  as  the  result  of  actual  observation  (p.  46)  that  the  longer  a  branch 
of  the  Sheffield  trades  has  been  in  union,  and  the  more  perfectly  it  has  been 
maintained,  the  higher  is  the  rate  of  remuneration  that  the  workmen  receive, 
the  lower  is  the  degree  of  fluctuation  in  the  trade,  and  the  greater  is  the  sobriety 
and  thrift  of  the  workers.      He  adds — "We  would  even  go  a  step  further  and 
contend,  that,  with  few  exceptions,  the  respectability  and  substantial  character 
of  the  manufacturers  exhibit  a  strict  relation  to  the  same   circumstances,   viz. 
the  degree  to  which  the  branch  is  associated.      The  system  which  gives  unlimited 
play  to  competition  not  only  lowers  wages  and  degrades  the  condition  of  the 
masses,   but  ultimately  reduces  profits,  narrows  the  liberality,  and  vitiates  the 
moral  tone  of  the  manufacturers."     Dr.  Calvert  Holland's  observations  upon  the 
actual  working  of  industrial  competition  appear  to  have  been  unknown,  or  at 
any  rate  unheeded,  by  the  economists  of  the  time. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  6 1 5 

of  monopoly  of  a  particular  service.  Such  a  monopoly  was 
plainly  inimical  to  the  interests  of  the  community.  The 
increased  drain  on  the  wage-fund  automatically  depressed 
the  wages  of  the  rest  of  the  wage-earners.  Their  exclusion 
from  the  ranks  of  the  favored  trade  further  intensified  their 
own  struggle  for  employment.  Finally,  as  capital  had  to 
receive  its  normal  rate  of  profit,  the  consumer  found  the 
price  of  the  commodity  raised  against  him.  Fortunately,  as 
the  economists  explained,  such  anti- social  conduct  could 
practically  never  succeed.  Even  if  the  monopolists  managed 
rigidly  to  exclude  new  competitors  from  their  trade,  the  rise 
in  price  would  attract  foreign  producers,  and  lead  to  an 
importation  of  the  commodity  from  abroad.  If  this  were 
prohibited,  the  consumer  would  begin  to  seek  alternatives 
for  a  commodity  which  had  become  too  dear  for  his  enjoy- 
ment, and  invention  would  set  to  work  to  produce  the  same 
result  by  new  processes,  employing  possibly  quite  a  different 
kind  of  labor.  One  way  or  another  the  monopolists  would 
be  certain  to  find  their  trade  shrinking  up,  so  that  a  mere 
exclusion  of  new-comers  would  no  longer  avail  them.  They 
would  find  it  impossible  to  maintain  their  exceptional  con- 
ditions except  by  progressively  reducing  their  own  numbers, 
to  the  point  even  of  ultimate  extinction. 

With  so  complete  a  demonstration  of  the  impossibility  of 
"  artificially "  raising  wages,  it  is  not  surprising  that  public 
opinion,  from  1825  down  to  about  1875,  condemned  im- 
partially all  the  methods  and  all  the  regulations  of  Trade 
Unionism.  To  the  ordinary  middle-class  man  it  seemed 
logically  indisputable  that  the  way  of  the  Trade  Unionists 
was  blocked  in  all  directions.  They  could  not  gain  any 
immediate  bettering  of  the  condition  of  the  whole  wage- 
earning  class,  because  the  amount  of  the  wage-fund  at  any 
given  time  was  predetermined.  They  could  not  permanently 
secure  better  terms  even  for  a  particular  section,  because  this 
would  cause  capital  immediately  to  begin  to  desert  that 
particular  trade  or  town.  They  could  not  make  any  real 
progress  in  the  near  future,  because  they  would  thereby 


616  Trade  Union  Theory 

check  the  accumulation  of  capital.  And  finally,  even  if  they 
could  persuade  a  benevolent  body  of  capitalists  to  augment 
wages  by  voluntarily  sharing  profits,  the  "  principle  of  popula- 
tion "  lay  in  wait  to  render  nugatory  any  such  new  form  of 
"  out-door  relief."  "  The  margin  for  the  possible  improve- 
ment of  [the  wage-earners']  lot,"  emphatically  declared  Cairnes 
in  1874,  "is  confined  within  narrow  barriers  which  cannot 
be  passed,  and  the  problem  of  their  elevation  is  hopeless. 
As  a  body  they  will  not  rise  at  all.  A  few,  more  energetic 
or  more  fortunate  than  the  rest,  will  from  time  to  time 
escape,  as  they  do  now,  from  the  ranks  of  their  fellows  to 
the  higher  walks  of  industrial  life,  but  the  great  majority  will 
remain  substantially  where  they  are.  The  remuneration  of 
labor  as  such,  skilled  or  unskilled^  can  never  rise  much  above  its 
present  level"  *  Trade  Unionism  was,  in  fact,  plainly  "  in 
this  dilemma,  that  whether  it  fails  or  whether  it  succeeds  in 
its  immediate  object,  its  ultimate  tendency  is  hurtful  to  the 
laborer.  If  it  fails,  at  once,  in  forcing  higher  terms  on  the 
employers  of  labor,  the  whole  cost  of  the  organisation,  in 
money  and  exertion,  is  simply  thrown  away.  ...  If,  on  the 
contrary,  it  should  attain,  for  a  time,  a  seeming  success,  the 
ultimate  result  is  even  worse.  Nature's  violated  laws  vindicate 
their  authority  by  a  sure  reaction.  The  presumptuous  mortal, 
who  dares  to  set  his  selfish  will  against  divine  ordinances, 
brings  on  his  head  inevitable  retribution  ;  his  momentary 
prosperity  disappears,  and  he  pays,  in  prolonged  suffering, 
the  penalty  of  his  suicidal  success."  2 

How  far    the  current  conceptions   of   economic   theory 

1  Some  Leading  Principles  of  Political  Economy  newly  expounded  (London, 
1874),  p.  348. 

2  Trade  Unionism^  by  James  Stirling,  p.  36.      "  The  bitter  hostility  to  trade 
unions,  which  at  any  rate  till  very  recent  years,  was  felt  by  the  *  upper '  and 
enlightened  classes,  was  doubtk-ss  chiefly  due  to  dislike  of  that  loss  of  the  more 
petty  delights  of  power  which  was  involved  in  the  substitution  of  the  relation  of 
buyer  and  seller  of  work  for  the  old  relation  of  master  and  servant,  but  it  was 
fostered    by  the  '  population  and  capital '  theory  of  wages,   which  really  made 
many  people  believe  that  associations  of  wage-earners,  however  annoying  and 
harmful  to  employers,  must  always  be  powerless  to  effect  any  improvement  in 
the  general  conditions  of  the  employed." — Edwin  Cannan,  History  of  the  Theories 
of  Production  and  Distribution  (London,  1893),  p.  393. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  6 1 7 

really  corresponded  with  the  views  of  the  best  economists 
of  this  period,  we  cannot  here  determine.  Some  of  these 
economists  seem  to  have  possessed  almost  a  genius  for 
publishing  what  they  did  not  mean  to  say,  and  the  wage-fund 
theory,  even  as  it  appeared  to  M'Culloch  and  Nassau  Senior, 
was  probably  very  far  from  the  mechanical  figment  of  the 
imagination  that  it  now  seems  to  us.  And  it  is  only  fair  to 
point  out  that  the  theory  of  wages,  which  to-day  fills  so  large 
a  place  in  economic  thought,  formed  only  an  incidental  and 
wholly  subordinate  part  of  the  teaching  of  the  classic 
economists.  Their  minds  were  directed  to  other  problems : 
to  the  evil  that  was  being  wrought  by  industrial  and  political 
restrictions,  which  the  generation  of  statesmen  whom  they 
taught  have  since  largely  removed.  Any  fair  appreciation  of 
their  teaching  is,  accordingly,  as  difficult  for  the  democracy 
of  to-day,  as  a  balanced  judgment  on  the  Mercantile  Theory 
was  to  Adam  Smith  and  his  immediate  followers.  Nor  was 
the  Wage  Fund  Theory  a  mere  wanton  invention.  It 
expressed  in  a  definite  formula  certain  salient  facts  of  the 
industry  of  that  generation.  The  English  farm  laborer  or 
factory  operative  was  obviously  dependent  on  the  wages 
advanced  to  him  week  by  week  out  of  his  employer's  capital. 
It  was  a  matter  of  common  observation  that  the  number  of 
laborers  taken  on  by  the  farmer,  or  of  operatives  by  the  mill- 
owner,  depended  on  the  amount  of  capital  that  he  could 
command.  At  a  time  of  rapidly  growing  population,  and 
manifold  new  inventions,  the  utmost  possible  increase  of 
capital  was  desirable,  whilst  the  evils  of  the  old  Poor  Law 
made  almost  inevitable  the  blind  adhesion  to  a  crude  Mal- 
thusianism.  The  theories  of  the  economists  corresponded 
with  the  prejudices  of  the  rising  middle  class,  and  seemed  to 
be  the  outcome  of  every  man's  experience. 

Meanwhile,  the  economists  themselves  were  undermining 
the  structure  which  they  had  hastily  erected.  Qualification 
after  qualification  was  introduced,  until  after  the  last  effort 
at  rehabilitation  by  Cairnes  in  1874,  the  whole  notion  of  a 
wage-fund  was  abandoned.  The  economic  text-books  written 


618  Trade  Union  Theory 

since  that  date1  deal  with  it,  if  at  all,  only  as  a  historical 
curiosity,  and  the  theory  of  distribution  which  has  taken  its 
place,  far  from  negativing  the  possibility  of  raising  the  con- 
dition of  the  wage-earners,  does  not  afford  even  a  presumption 
against  wisely-directed  Trade  Union  action.  But  the  dis- 
coveries of  the  economists  have  penetrated  only  slowly  and 
imperfectly  into  the  public  mind,  and  most  of  the  current 
opposition  to  Trade  Unionism  is  still  implicitly  based  on  the 
old  theory.  We  must  therefore,  at  the  risk  of  wearying  the 
economic  student,  explain,  in  some  detail,  how  it  breaks 
down  at  every  point.2 

Let  us  consider  first  the  statical  notion  of  a  predetermined 
wage-fund.  It  does  not  seem  to  have  occurred  to  the 
inventors  of  this  figment  that,  whatever  limit  it  might  set  to 
the  advances  made  to  the  laborers  during  the  year,  it  in  no 
way  determined  the  total  amount  of  their  remuneration  for 
the  year.  Even  if  the  farmer's  payments  for  labor  up  to  the 
harvest  had  to  be  restricted  to  a  limited  portion  of  last  year's 
product,  this  did  not  prevent  him  from  distributing  among 
the  laborers,  at  Martinmas  (the  usual  end  of  the  yearly 
hiring),  in  addition  to  these  advances,  some  part  of  the  harvest 
just  reaped.  As  many  economists  have  since  pointed  out, 

1  We  may  cite,  for  instance,  the  economic  text-books  or  treatises  of  Professors 
Marshall,  Nicholson,  Conner,  Mavor,  Smart,  and  Symes. 

2  It  is  pointed  out  by  Cannan,  Taussig,  and  F.  A.  Walker,  that  the  Wage 
Fund  Theory  was  never  accepted,  to  name  only  writers  in  English,  by  W. 
Thompson,  R.   Jones,  T.    C.   Banfield,  Montifort   Longfield,   H.  D.    Macleod, 
Cliffe  Leslie,  John  Ruskin,  or  Thorold  Rogers  in  our  own  country,  or  by  Dr. 
Wayland,  Amasa  Walker,  Bowen,  Daniel  Raymond,  and  Erasmus  Peshine  Smith 
in  America.     It  was  trenchantly  attacked,  not  only  by  the  Trade  Unionists,  the 
Christian  Socialists,  and  the  Positivists  (see,  for  instance,  T.  J.  Dunning's  Trade 
Unions:    their   Philosophy  and  Intention    (London,    1860),   a  work    read    and 
praised,  but  not  heeded,  by  J.    S.   Mill ;  J.    M.    Ludlow's   Christian  Socialism 
(London,  1851);  and  the  admirable  articles  on  Political  Economy  by  Frederic 
Harrison  in  the  Fortnightly  Review  for  1867),  but  also  explicitly  in  the  language 
of  abstract  economics  by  Fleeming  Jenkin  in  March  1868,  in  an  article  in  the 
North  British  Revieiv  ("Trade  Unions:  how  far  Legitimate"),  and  especially 
by  F.  D.  Longe  in  1866,  in  his  Refutation  of  the  Wages  Fund  Theory  of  Modern 
Political  Economy ',  as  enunciated  by  Mr.  Mill  and  Mr.  Fawcett  (London,  1866). 
The  well-known  attack  by  W.  T.  Thornton,  entitled  On  Labour,  its  Wrongful 
Claims  and  Rightful  Dues,  its  Actual  Present  and  Possible  Future  (London, 
1869),  and  the  immediate  recantation  of  the  Wage  Fund  Theory  by  J.  S.  Mill, 
first  really  attracted  economic  attention  to  the  subject. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  619 

no  inconsiderable  proportion  of  the  world's  laborers,  especially 
in  the  whaling,  fishing,  and  mining  industries,  are  actually 
engaged  on  "  shares,"  and  find  the  amount  of  the  last  instal- 
ments of  their  wages  for  the  whole  venture  both  regulated 
by,  and  paid  out  of,  the  sum  of  utilities  which  they  have 
themselves  created.1  Thus,  even  if  there  existed  any  pre- 
determined portion  of  capital  definitely  ear-marked  as  the 
wage-fund,  it  would  still  be  only  the  measure  of  advances, 
not  of  wages  ;  its  amount  would  throw  no  light  upon  the 
proportion  of  the  income  of  the  community  which  is  obtained 
by  the  wage-earning  class  ;  and  its  limitation  would  in  no 
wise  stand  in  the  way  of  the  year's  remuneration  of  the  class 
as  a  whole  being  indefinitely  augmented  at  the  end  of  each 
year,  or  on  the  completion  of  each  undertaking,  not  out  of 
previously  accumulated  capital,  but  actually  out  of  their 
own  product. 

But  there  is,  in  fact,  no  such  predetermined  amount 
applicable  for  the  payment  of  wages,  still  less  any  fund  set 
apart  at  the  beginning  of  each  year,  or  any  other  period.  The 
wage-earners  of  the  world  are  not,  any  more  than  the 
capitalists  of  the  world,  fed  for  the  entire  year  out  of  a  store 
of  food  and  other  necessaries,  or  paid  out  of  an  accumulated 
fund  of  capital,  actually  in  hand  at  the  beginning  of  the  year. 
Whatever  may  be  the  tasks  on  which  the  workmen  are 
engaged,  they  are,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  fed,  week  by  week,  by 
products  just  brought  to  market,  exactly  in  the  same  way 
as  the  employer  and  his  household  are  fed.  They  are  paid 
their  wages,  week  by  week,  out  of  the  current  cash  balances 
of  their  employers,  these  cash  balances  being  daily  replenished 
by  sales  of  the  current  product.  The  weekly  drawings  of  the 
several  partners  in  a  firm  come  from  precisely  the  same  fund 
as  the  wages  of  their  workpeople.  Whether  or  not  any 
assignable  limits  can  be  set  to  the  possible  expansion  of  this 
source  of  current  income,  it  will  be  at  once  evident  that  there 
is  no  arithmetical  impossibility  in  the  workmen  obtaining  a 

1  This  supplies  Mr.  Henry  George  (Progress  and  Poverty]  with  some  of  his 
most  telling  demonstrations  of  the  futility  of  the  wage-fund  theory. 


62O  Trade  Union  Theory 

larger,  and  the  employers  a  smaller,  proportion  of  the  total 
drawings  for  any  particular  week.  If  all  the  hired  laborers 
in  the  world  were,  suddenly  and  simultaneously,  to  insist  on 
a  general  rise  of  wages,  there  is  no  mathematical  impossibility 
in  the  rise  being  contemporaneously  balanced  by  an  equal 
reduction  in  the  aggregate  current  drawings  of  the  employers. 
If  the  world's  current  supply  of  food  and  other  necessaries  be 
supposed  to  be  the  limit,  what  is  there  to  prevent  the  con- 
sumption of  the  employers  and  their  families  from  being 
diminished  ?  Accordingly  we  find  John  Stuart  Mill,  in  his 
celebrated  review  of  Thornton's  book,  unreservedly  abandon- 
ing the  very  notion  of  any  predetermined  wage-fund.  "  There 
is  no  law  of  nature  making  it  inherently  impossible  for  wages 
to  rise  to  the  point  of  absorbing,  not  only  the  funds  which 
[the  employer]  had  intended  to  devote  to  carrying  on  his 
business,  but  the  whole  of  what  he  allows  for  his  private 
expenses  beyond  the  necessaries  of  life.  ...  In  short,  there 
is  abstractedly  available  for  the  payment  of  wages,  before  an 
absolute  limit  is  reached,  not  only  the  employer's  capital,  but 
the  whole  of  what  can  possibly  be  retrenched  from  his  private 
expenditure,  and  the  law  of  wages  on  the  side  of  demand 
amounts  only  to  the  obvious  proposition  that  the  employers 
cannot  pay  away  in  wages  what  they  have  not  got.  .  .  . 
The  power  of  Trade  Unions  may,  therefore,  be  so  exercised 
as  to  obtain  for  the  laboring  classes  collectively  both  a  larger 
share  and  a  larger  positive  amount  of  the  produce  of 
labor."  1 

But  though  it  was  this  statical  conception  of  a  definitely 
limited  special  wage-fund  which  gave  the  educated  public 
its  "  cocksureness  "  against  the  workmen,  most  of  the  econo- 
mists themselves  probably  laid  more  stress  on  what  we  have 
termed  the  dynamic  aspect  of  the  theory.  If  the  laborers 
compelled  the  employers  to  agree  to  give  them  better  terms 
for  the  future,  this  very  rise  of  wages,  causing  a  correspond- 
ing fall  in  profits,  would,  it  was  argued,  cause  such  a  diminu- 

1  J.  S.  Mill,  Fortnightly  Review,  May  1869  ;  Dissertations  and  Discussions, 
vol.  iv.  pp.  46,  48. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  621 

tion  of  saving  as  would  presently  counteract  the  rise.  Thus 
it  followed  that  the  rate  of  profit  on  capital,  together  with 
the  rate  of  wages,  was,  in  any  given  state  of  mind  of  the 
saving  class,  really  unalterable.  Any  accidental  variation  in 
the  general  rate  of  profit,  whether  upward  or  downward, 
automatically  set  up  a  reaction  which  continued  until  the 
normal  was  again  reached.  "  Two  antagonistic  forces,"  it 
was  said,  "  hold  the  industrial  world  in  equilibrio.  On  the 
one  hand,  the  principle  of  population  regulates  the  supply 
of  labor ;  on  the  other,  the  principle  of  accumulation 
determines  the  demand  for  it."  1 

Now,  before  examining  this  theory  point  by  point,  we 
note  that  it  contains  a  series  of  assumptions  which  were 
neither  explicitly  stated  nor  in  any  way  proved.  It  takes 
for  granted,  in  the  first  place,  that  Trade  Union  action  must 
necessarily  diminish  profits ;  an  assumption  which  simply 
ignores  the  Trade  Union  claim — considered  at  length  in  the 
next  two  chapters — that  the  enforcement  of  a  Common  Rule 
positively  increases  the  efficiency  of  industry.  Secondly, 
we  have  the  assumption  that  a  diminution  of  profits 
necessarily  implies  a  fall  in  the  rate  of  interest  on  capital, 
thus  leaving  out  of  account  the  possibility  that  a  rise  of 
wages  might  mean  simply  an  alteration  in  the  shares  of 
different  grades  of  producers,  the  entrepreneur  class  (and  not 
the  mere  investor)  losing  what  the  manual  workers  gain. 
Finally,  we  have  the  assumption  that  the  heaping  up  of 
material  wealth  is  the  only  way  of  increasing  the  national 
capital.  "  The  older  economists,"  says  Professor  Marshall, 
"  went  too  far  in  suggesting  that  a  rise  in  interest  (or  of 
profits)  at  the  expense  of  wages  always  increased  the  power 
of  saving ;  they  forgot  that  from  the  national  point  of  view 
the  investment  of  wealth  in  the  child  of  the  working  man  is 
as  productive  as  its  investment  in  horses  and  machinery.  .  .  . 
The  middle,  and  especially  the  professional  classes  have 
always  denied  themselves  much  in  order  to  invest  capital  in 
the  education  of  their  children,  while  a  great  part  of  the 

1    Trade  Unionism^  by  James  Stirling,  p.  26. 


622  Trade  Union  Theory 

wages  of  the  working   classes  is   invested    in   the    physical 
health  and  strength  of  their  children."  l 

But  is  it  true  that  the  growth  of  capital  depends  on  the 
rate  of  interest,  so  that  "  the  greater  the  proportion  of  wages 
to  profits, the  smaller  the  tendency  to  national  accumulation"?2 
Does  the  "  motive  for  accumulation "  diminish,  as  Ricardo 
incidentally  declared,  "  with  every  diminution  of  profit "  ? 3 
The  great  investigators  who  preceded  Ricardo  held  an 
exactly  opposite  view.  Sir  Josiah  Child  remarked  two 
centuries  ago  that  the  extremely  low  rate  of  interest  in  the 
Netherlands  towards  the  close  of  the  seventeenth  century, 
far  from  diminishing  accumulation,  "  was  the  causa  causans  of 
all  the  other  causes  of  the  riches  of  the  Dutch  people."  In 
countries  where  the  rate  of  interest  was  high,  he  observed 
that  "  merchants,  when  they  have  gotten  great  wealth,  leave 
trading,  and  lend  out  their  money  at  interest,  the  gain 
thereof  being  so  easy,  certain,  and  great ;  whereas  in  other 
countries,  where  interest  is  at  a  lower  rate,  they  con- 
tinue merchants  from  generation  to  generation,  and  enrich 
themselves  and  the  State."  4  "  Low  interest,"  he  emphatically 

1  Principles  of  Economics,  3rd  edition  (London,  1895),  Book  IV.  chap.  vii.  pp. 
311,  318.     The  Trade  Unionist  may  very  well  complain  that  the  economists  had, 
at  any  rate,  no  warrant  for  the  definiteness  of  their  assumptions.     Even  if  it  be 
granted  that  a  fall  in  the  rate  of  interest  tends  to  diminish  the  amount  saved,  no 
reason  has  been  given  for  the  supposition  that  any  particular  rise  in  the  rate  of 
wages  would  necessarily  tend  to  slacken  accumulation  precisely  to  such  an  extent  as 
to  cause  wages  to  fall  hereafter  by  the  amount  of  the  rise.      If,  for  instance,  wages 
rose  generally  by  10  per  cent,  and  the  cost  fell  entirely  on  interest,  by  how  much 
per  cent  would  the  rate  be  thereby  lowered  ?     If  it  lowered  the  rate  from  3  to  2^ 
per  cent,  by  how  much  would  the  amount  saved  annually  be  reduced?     If  it 
reduced  the  amount  saved  annually  from  200  millions  to   175  millions,  by  how 
much  would  the  general  rate  of  wages  be  therefore  lowered  ?     To  none  of  these 
questions  can  even  an  approximate  answer  be  given.     The  tacit  assumption  of 
the  economists  that,  other  things  remaining  equal,  a  rise  in  wages  of  10  per  cent 
would  necessarily  produce  such  a  fall  in  the  rate  of  interest  as  would  result  in 
such  a  diminution  of  the  amount  annually  saved  as  would  cause  wages  to  fall 
again  by  at  least  10  per  cent,  will  probably  be  considered  by  future  ages  as  one 
of  the  most  extraordinary  chains  of  hypothetical  reasoning  ever  resorted  to. 

2  Trade  Unionism,  by  James  Stirling,  pp.  28,  29. 

3  On  the  Principles  of  Political  Economy  and  Taxation  (London,  1817),  p.  136. 

4  A  New  Discourse  of  Trade,  2nd  edition  (London,  1694),  p.  8  ;  quoted  in 
Principles  of  Economics,  by  Professor  A.  Marshall,  Book  IV.  ch.  vii.  p.  316  of 
3rd  edition  (London,  1895). 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  623 

declared,  "is  the  natural  mother  of  Frugality,  Industry, 
and  the  Arts."1  In  Adam  Smith's  opinion  a  high  rate 
of  profit  was  in  many  ways  positively  injurious  to  national 
wealth.  "  But  besides  all  the  bad  effects  to  the  country 
in  general,"  said  he,  "which  have  already  been  mentioned 
as  resulting  from  a  high  rate  of  profit,  there  is  one  more 
fatal,  perhaps,  than  all  these  put  together,  but  which,  if  we 
may  judge  from  experience,  is  inseparably  connected  with 
it.  The  high  rate  of  profit  seems  everywhere  to  destroy 
that  parsimony  which  in  other  circumstances  is  natural  to 
the  character  of  the  merchant.  When  profits  are  high  that 
sober  virtue  seems  to  be  superfluous,  and  expensive  luxury 
to  suit  better  the  affluence  of  his  situation.  .  .  .  Accumula- 
tion is  thus  prevented  in  the  hands  of  all  those  who  are 
naturally  the  most  disposed  to  accumulate  ;  and  the  funds 
destined  for  the  maintenance  of  productive  labor  receive  no 
augmentation  from  the  revenue  of  those  who  ought  naturally 
to  augment  them  the  most.  .  .  .  Light  come  light  go,  says 
the  proverb  ;  and  the  ordinary  tone  of  expense  seems  every- 
where to  be  regulated,  not  so  much  according  to  the  real 
ability  of  spending,  as  to  the  supposed  facility  of  getting 
money  to  spend." 2  Thus  he  infers  that,  after  the  "  profits 
on  stock  "  or  capital  "  are  diminished,  stock  may  not  only 
continue  to  increase,  but  to  increase  much  faster  than 
before  "  ! 3 

1  A  New  Discourse  of  Trade,  2nd  edition  (London,  1694),  preface. 

2  Adam   Smith,    Wealth  of  Nations  (London,   1776),  Book   IV.  chap.  vii. 
p.  276  of  M'Culloch's  edition. 

3  Ibid.  Book  I.  chap.  ix.  p.  42. 

The  contrary  assumption,  on  which  so  much  of  the  opposition  to  Trade 
Unionism  is  still  based,  was,  until  1848,  more  often  implied  than  explicitly  stated 
in  economic  treatises.  Nassau  Senior,  who  introduced  to  economics  the  term 
"reward  of  abstinence,"  nowhere  makes  the  statement  that  the  amount  of  saving 
varies  with  the  rate  of  profit  or  interest.  "  Capitals,"  he  says  in  one  place, 
"are  generally  formed  from  small  beginnings  by  acts  of  accumulation  which 
become  in  time  habitual,"  and  in  the  hypothetical  example  he  gives  he  actually 
assumes  that  a  decrease  in  the  rate  of  profit  will  apply  a  new  stimulus  to  accumu- 
lation (Political  Economy,  p.  192).  M'Culloch,  too,  regarded  the  amount  of 
accumulation  as  depending  only  on  the  extent  of  the  margin  for  saving,  not  upon 
the  expectation  of  a  high  rate  of  interest  or  profit.  "  The  means  of  amassing 
capital  will  be  greatest  .  .  .  where  the  net  profits  of  stock  are  greatest.  .  .  . 


624  Trade  Union  Theory 

The  modern  economist  finds,  in  the  actual  facts  of 
industrial  life,  much  that  supports  this  view.  It  may  be 
true  that  here  and  there  a  capitalist  employer,  especially  a 
manufacturer  or  a  farmer,  will  strive  harder  to  increase  his 
capital  if  he  sees  the  prospect  of  exceptional  profit,  than  if 
he  can  only  just  pay  his  way,  though  on  the  other  side  must 
be  set  the  fact  that  in  this  class  high  profits  notoriously  lead 
to  extravagant  personal  expenditure,  and  that  it  is,  as  Adam 
Smith  pointed  out,  not  during  periods  of  high  profits,  but 
rather  in  bad  times,  that  luxuries  are  retrenched.  But  there 
is  reason  to  believe  that  a  large  part — in  these  days  perhaps 
the  greater  part — of  the  saving  of  the  world  takes  place  quite 
irrespective  of  the  rate  of  interest  that  can  be  obtained  for 
the  use  of  the  capital.  The  strongest  motives  for  saving — 
the  desire  to  provide  for  sickness  and  old  age,  or  for  the 
future  maintenance  of  children — go  on,  as  the  hoards  of  the 
French  peasantry  show,  whether  profit  or  interest  is  reaped 
or  not.  The  whole  history  of  popular  savings  banks  demon- 
strates that  what  is  sought  by  the  great  bulk  of  the  investing 
population  is  security  for  their  savings,  not  any  particular 
rate  of  interest.  It  is,  in  fact,  within  the  experience  of  every 
savings  bank  that  some  depositors,  content  to  get  this 
security  only,  persist  in  increasing  their  deposits  over  the 
maximum  on  which  any  interest  is  paid.  No  reduction  in 
the  rate  of  savings  bank  interest  ever  causes  anything  like 
a  proportionate  reduction  in  the  amount  of  the  deposits  ; 
usually,  indeed,  it  causes  no  visible  reduction  at  all.  At  the 
other  end  of  the  social  scale,  though  possibly  for  a  different 
reason,  accumulation  appears  to  proceed  with  equal  indiffer- 

Give  to  any  people  the  power  of  accumulating,  and  we  may  depend  upon  it  they 
will  not  be  disinclined  to  use  it  effectively.  .  .  .  No  instance  can  be  produced  of 
any  people  having  ever  missed  an  opportunity  to  amass." — Principles  of  Political 
Economy,  1825,  part  ii.  sec.  2. 

Mr.  Cannan  has  drawn  our  attention  to  an  article  by  W.  Ellis  in  the  West- 
minster Review  for  January  1826,  which  contains  the  first  clear  expression  of  the 
other  view.  J.  S.  Mill  seems  to  have  been  the  first  systematic  economist  in 
England  to  give  definite  form  to  the  statement  that  the  rate  of  accumulation  would, 
in  any  given  state  of  wealth  and  habit  of  mind,  vary  with  the  rate  of  interest  to 
be  expected  from  capital. — Principles  of  Political  Economy,  Book  I.  chap.  xi. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  ^ 


ence  to  the  rate  of  prot      Ti, 

and  Vanderbilts,  the  SrftaTS^  ^''^  °f  ^  Astors 
the  Cavendishes  and'c  *>^  ^^^  °f  income  by 
*ons  of  the  Rothschilds,  donT  as  a  "T^  aCCUm"Ia- 
on  how  much  per  cent  the*  I'M-  °f  fact>  depend 

^  their  new  capita],  but  tthe  ^'^  6XpeCt  to  %* 
over  and  above  their  curren"  S^T*  °f  Sheer  SUrP'»s 
'°  say  the  least  of  it  extre  i  j  °f  exPe"diture.  ft  is 

'arge  c,ass  whose  fnco^f  L  "ttji  "''  "  "^  a"  ^ 
need  or  desire  to  ^e£^  In  excess  of  what  they 

th's  year  will  be  S^fS^^0^^  they  inv  J 
•nterest  will  be  4  instead  of  3  ^0^°'  \*&t  the  rate  of 
expected  that  the  rate  will   be  onl^  ,         dlrain'^ed  if  it  is 
F'nally,  there  is  a  third  type  of  f  2  'nStead  of  3  per  cent. 
a"y  change  in  the  rate  of  profi°  i,        ?•  ^  the  effect  of 
d-rection,  the  amount  of  accutu  I^T  7  "  *he  °PP°site 
fall  m  the  rate,  and  checked  h  bei"g  increased  by  a 

-ving  of  the  world  fa^wW,  t^     A  ^  P&rt  °f  ^ 
some   future   time,  an  incL  m°tlve  of  obtaining  at 

a 


to  retire 


amy  in  a  country  malon  O  a  ^ear  '°  main- 

°r  'f  the  recognised  portio^for        u    the  ECcePted  stamp 


a 

ccumulation  of  capital      «  A"  ff°  P°SltiveIy  stimulated 
VOL.  ii  As  the  rate  of  interest  falls," 


2  S 


626  Trade  Union  Theory 

says  Professor  Smart,  "  the  motive  of  the  richer  classes  to  save 
rather  than  to  consume  grows  stronger." l  And  it  must  not 
be  forgotten  that  every  fall  in  the  rate  of  interest,  by  affording 
new  opportunities  for  its  profitable  investment  in  appliances 
for  increasing  the  productivity  of  labor,  stimulates  the  desire 
to  invest  and  presently  increases  the  power  to  save.  Under 
this  head  must  come,  too,  the  large  and  ever- increasing 
form  of  compulsory  saving  which  is  represented  by  public 
outlay  on  permanent  works  of  utility.  When  a  municipality 
engages  in  large  public  works,  it  does  more  than  find  useful 
investment  for  savings  which  would  in  any  case  have  been 
made.  By  making  arrangements  for  repaying  the  loan 
within  a  definite  number  of  years — in  England,  on  an  average 
about  thirty — the  ratepayers,  besides  paying  the  interest, 
find  themselves  compelled  to  put  by  for  the  community,  out 
of  their  individual  incomes,  before  they  can  begin  to  save 
for  themselves  at  all,  a  sum  equal  to  the  annual  repayment 
of  debt.  It  can  scarcely  be  doubted  that  this  compulsory 
saving,  which  no  individual  ratepayer  regards  as  saving  at 
all,  is,  like  taxation  generally,  to  a  large  extent  retrenched 
from  current  personal  expenditure,  and  is  therefore,  to  this 
extent,  a  clear  addition  to  the  capital  of  the  community. 
Now,  the  extent  to  which  municipalities  will  raise  loans  for 
public  works,  to  be  thus  made  up  by  compulsory  savings, 
depends  in  a  very  large  degree  on  the  rate  of  interest,  rising 
when  that  falls  and  falling  when  that  rises.  "  Accordingly," 
concludes  Professor  Nicholson,  "we  cannot  strictly  speak  of 
a  particular  minimum  rate  in  any  society  as  necessary  to 
accumulation  in  general ;  and  if  Adam  Smith's  opinion  is 
well  founded,  we  cannot  even  say  that  a  rise  in  the  rate  of 
interest  will  increase,  or  a  fall  check  accumulation.  .  .  .  The 
growth  of  material  capital  depends  upon  a  number  of  vari- 
ables, of  which  the  rate  of  interest  is  only  one,  and  is, 
furthermore,  indeterminate  in  its  effect? 2  To  put  it  con- 

1  Studies  in  Economics  (London,  1895),  p.  297. 

2  J.  S.  Nicholson,  Principles  of  Political  Economy  ^&\rfo\xgs\i  1893),  P-  394- 
Sir  Josiah  Child  went  so  far  as  to  predict  that  "  the  bringing  down  of  interest  in 
this  kingdom  from  six  to  four  or  three  per  cent  will  necessarily,  in  less  than 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  627 

cretely,  it  is,  to  say  the  least  of  it,  extremely  doubtful 
whether  the  accumulated  capital  of  the  United  Kingdom 
would  be  greater  or  less  at  the  present  time  if  the  rate  of 
interest  on  the  best  security,  instead  of  falling  to  a  little  over 
2  per  cent,  had  remained  at  5  or  6  per  cent,  the  rate  at  which 
Pitt  frequently  issued  Consols.  Still  less  is  it  possible  for 
the  economist  to  predict  whether,  our  national  habits  being 
as  they  are,  the  growth  in  wealth  during  the  next  hundred 
years  would  be  stimulated  or  depressed  if  the  rate  should 
within  that  period  fall  even  to  I  per  cent.  Considering,  there- 
fore, that  the  very  poor  and  the  very  rich  are,  as  regards 
the  actual  accumulation  of  material  wealth,  practically  unin- 
fluenced either  way ;  that  an  increase  of  wages  is  likely 
positively  to  increase  that  highly  productive  form  of  the 
nation's  capital,  the  physical  strength  and  mental  training 
of  the  manual  working  class  ;  that  the  middle  class  is  mainly 
bent  on  securing  permanent  incomes  for  future  maintenance, 
and  will  therefore  be  induced  to  work  longer  and  harder,  and 
save  more,  the  lower  the  rate  of  interest  descends ;  that  a 
low  rate  of  interest  both  stimulates  inventions  and  promotes 
their  general  adoption ;  and  that  municipal  and  national 
enterprise,  if  favored  by  a  low  rate  of  interest,  grows  by  leaps 
and  bounds,  economists  are  beginning  to  assert  that  a  rise  of 
wages  at  the  expense  of  profits  would  probably  result,  not  in 
less,  but  actually  in  more  being  produced,  and  taking  all 
forms  of  national  wealth  into  account,  that  it  might  be 
expected  positively  to  increase  the  productive  capital  of  the 
community  in  one  form  or  another.  We  do  not  understand 
whether  Professor  Marshall  goes  this  length,  but  "  we  may 
conclude,"  he  says,  "  in  opposition  to  [the  older  economists], 
that  any  change  in  the  distribution  of  wealth  which  gives 
more  to  the  wage -receivers  and  less  to  the  capitalists  is 
likely,  other  things  being  equal,  to  hasten  the  increase  of 
material  production,  and  that  it  will  not  perceptibly  retard  the 
storing-up  of  material  wealth."  * 

twenty  years'  time,  double  the  capital  stock  of  the  nation." — A  New  Discourse  of 
Trade,  2nd  edition  (London,  1694),  p.  14. 

1  Principles  of  Economics,  by  Professor  A.   Marshall,  3rd  edition  (London, 


628  Trade  Union  Theory 

So  far  the  modern  economic  criticism  of  the  current 
middle-class  view  takes  account  only  of  a  general  bettering 
of  the  conditions  of  labor  and  a  general  fall  in  the  rate  of 
profit  in  all  trades.  If  now  we  consider  the  more  usual  case 
of  an  alteration  in  the  profitableness  of  a  particular  industry, 
the  modern  student  finds  it  equally  impossible  to  come  to  a 
dogmatic  conclusion  against  Trade  Unionism.  The  older 
economists  made  the  convenient  assumption  that  both 
capital  and  labor  were  freely  mobile  as  between  one  trade 
and  another,  and  that  it  was  therefore  impossible  for  any 
important  variations  between  wages  and  profits  in  different 
trades  to  be  of  long  continuance.  Here,  again,  the  popular 
argument  against  Trade  Unionism  ignored  the  all-important 
element  of  time.  If  the  employers  in  one  industry  happened 
to  make  large  profits,  additional  capital,  it  was  said,  would 
flow  into  that  trade,  and  the  workmen  would  thus,  sooner  or 
later,  find  the  demand  for  their  services  increased  and  their 
wages  raised.  But  why  should  the  workmen  wait?  On 
the  economist's  own  showing,  there  would  be  nothing  to 
prevent  a  combination  of  all  the  workmen  in  the  trade 
taking  advantage  of  the  golden  opportunity  when  profits 
were  high,  and  so  increasing  their  wages  as  to  absorb  a 
large  share  of  this  surplus  for  themselves.1  There  would 
then  be  no  attraction  for  additional  capital  to  enter  the 
trade,  and  therefore  no  reason  why  the  surplus  should  not 
continue  to  exist,  to  the  benefit  of  the  workmen  in  that  trade. 
Their  wages  would  have  risen  relatively  to  those  in  other 
trades,  with  the  result  that  new  workmen  would  be  attracted 
to  it.  But  it  is  not  easy  for  men  to  change  their  trades 

1895),  Book  IV.  chap.  vii.  p.  311.  Some  economists  are  beginning  to  suggest 
that  the  world's  stock  of  capital  is  largely  determined  by  the  world's  need  of  capital 
— accumulation  beyond  industrial  requirements  automatically  causing  destruction 
of  other  capital.  See  the,  on  this  point,  suggestive  works  of  Mr.  J.  A.  Hobson. 
1  "  When  profits  rise  in  any  branch  of  trade  above  the  usual  rate,  the 
masters  evidently  could,  if  they  chose,  afford  to  make  over  to  the  men  as 
additional  wages,  the  whole  difference  between  their  old  and  their  new  profits. 
They  could  do  this  if  they  pleased  without  reducing  profits  below  the  previously 
current  and  usual  rate.  And  being  able  to  do  this  it  is  conceivable  that  they 
might  by  a  powerful  union  be  constrained  to  do  it." — W.  T.  Thornton,  On 
Labour  (London,  1870),  pp.  284,  285. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  629 

with  advantage,  especially  among  the  skilled  crafts,  and  it 
would  take  some  years  before  the  increased  attractiveness  of 
the  better-paid  trade  among  boys  choosing  their  occupations 
caused  any  appreciable  increase  in  the  number  of  journey- 
men. Moreover,  this  would  be  a  clear  case  in  which  a 
Trade  Union  might  by  close  combination  or  legal  enactment 
better  its  conditions  of  employment  without  decreasing  the 
amount  of  work  for  its  own  members,  and  without  depriving 
the  rest  of  the  wage-earners  of  anything  that  they  could 
otherwise  have  obtained.  All  that  would  then  have  happened 
would  be  that  an  increase  in  profits,  which  would  otherwise 
have  gone  first  to  the  capitalists,  and  eventually  to  the  con- 
sumers, would  have  been  lastingly  secured  by  a  section  of  the 
workpeople.  Hence  the  economist's  own  reasoning  seems  to 
bear  out  the  workmen's  empirical  conclusion, that  Trade  Union 
action  is  most  strikingly  successful  when  it  takes  the  form  of 
claiming  advances  at  the  moment  that  trade  is  profitable. 

When  we  consider  the  country  as  a  whole,  in  its  com- 
petition with  other  countries,  the  argument,  though  more 
complicated,  is  equally  inconclusive.  If  the  wage-earners  of 
one  country  obtain,  whether  by  law  or  by  negotiation,  better 
sanitation,  shorter  hours,  or  higher  wages  than  their  colleagues 
in  other  countries,  and  if  these  better  terms  for  labor  involve 
a  lower  rate  of  profit  on  capital,  it  is  suggested  that  capital 
will  "  flow "  out  of  the  relatively  unprofitable  country,  in 
order  to  seek  investment  abroad.  The  improvement  of  the 
conditions  of  labor  would,  under  these  circumstances,  be 
temporary  only,  as  the  resulting  diminution  of  profits  would 
bring  about  its  own  cure.  To  the  modern  financial  expert, 
actually  engaged  in  international  transactions,  this  contention 
seems  highly  problematical.  He  sees  the  rates  of  business 
profits  in  different  countries  remain  permanently  divergent, 
two  or  three  times  as  much  being  habitually  earned  by 
capitalist  enterprises  in  one  country,  as  compared  with  similar 
enterprises  in  another.  In  spite  of  the  assumed  international 
mobility  of  capital,  even  the  rates  of  loan  interest  in  different 
countries  remain  very  far  from  equality.  And  though  capital 


630  Trade  Union  Theory 

flows  here  and  there  from  time  to  time,  the  expert  financier 
detects  nothing  in  the  nature  of  that  promptly  -  flowing 
current  from  low-rate  countries  to  high-rate  countries  which 
might  be  expected  to  bring  the  divergence  quickly  to  an 
end,  and  which  was  assumed  without  evidence  by  a  more 
theoretic  generation.  His  usual  explanation  is  that,  here  as 
elsewhere,  it  is  far  more  important  to  the  investor  of  capital 
to  obtain  security  than  to  gain  an  increased  rate  of  interest. 
This  security  depends  upon  a  great  variety  of  considerations, 
among  which,  in  these  democratic  days,  not  the  least  im- 
portant is  the  state  of  mind  of  the  wage-earning  class. 
Hence  an  improvement  in  the  conditions  of  employment, 
made  at  the  cost  of  the  capitalist,  far  from  necessarily  driving 
more  capital  abroad,  as  Cairnes  imagined,  may  positively 
tend  to 'keep  it  at  home.  Factory  legislation,  compulsory 
sanitation,  short  hours  of  labor,  a  high  level  of  wages,  freedom 
of  combination,  and  generally  the  habit  of  treating  the  wage- 
earners  with  consideration,  may  seem  to  make  capital  yield 
a  lower  annual  return  to  the  investor  than  might  be  gained 
in  other  countries.  But  if  these  things  result  in  political 
and  social  stability,  if  they  increase  the  amenity  of  life,  and 
especially  if  they  promise  to  erect  a  bulwark  against  revolu- 
tion and  spoliation,  the  investor  will,  as  a  matter  of  fact, 
prefer  to  see  his  rate  of  interest  gradually  decline  if  the 
reduction  is  accompanied  by  an  increase  in  political  security, 
rather  than  seek  higher  gains  in  more  discontented,  and 
therefore  less  stable  communities.  Thus  the  reaction  set  up 
by  a  bettering  of  the  condition  of  the  English  workmen  at 
the  cost  of  the  capitalist  may  be  quite  in  the  reverse 
direction  to  that  formerly  imagined.  But  there  is  another, 
and,  as  we  think,  more  important  reason  for  the  apparently 
inexplicable  divergence  between  the  rates  earned  by  capital  in 
different  countries.  Capital  does  not  of  itself  produce  either 
profit  or  interest,  and  can  only  really  be  used  to  advantage 
when  it  is  employed  in  conjunction  with  an  efficient  organ- 
isation of  industry,  an  adequate  supply  of  skilled  workmen, 
and  the  ^dispensable  element  of  business  ability.  It  is 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  631 

probable  that  the  profitableness  of  English  industry  would 
be  far  more  endangered  by  the  emigration  of  all  its  skilled 
craftsmen,  or  the  desertion  of  its  genuine  captains  ot 
industry,  than  by  any  merely  mechanical  investments  in 
foreign  lands.  An  increase  of  wages,  by  keeping  at  home 
the  most  energetic  and  ingenious  workmen,  who  might  other- 
wise have  emigrated,  thus  tends  positively  to  increase  profits 
in  England.  But  the  migration  of  skilled  workmen,  and 
still  more,  that  of  brain-power,  from  one  country  to  another, 
depends  on  many  other  motives  than  the  rate  of  pecuniary 
reward.  Here,  again,  the  reaction  set  up  by  a  fall  in  the 
rate  of  profit  may  be  quite  in  the  contrary  direction  to  that 
formerly  supposed.  If  an  improvement  in  the  condition  of 
the  English  working  classes  adds  to  the  amenity  of  English 
life,  it  may  increase  the  attractiveness  of  England  to  the  able 
business  man,  and  so  in  this  way  positively  increase  the 
profitableness  of  English  industry,  and  hence  the  reward  of 
the  capitalist  and  brain-worker,  by  far  more  than  the  improve- 
ment has  cost.  Where  the  business  capacity  is  to  be  found, 
there,  in  the  long  run,  will  be  the  capital.  We  need  not 
therefore  be  surprised  to  learn  that  there  is  absolutely  no 
evidence  that  the  past  fifty  years'  rise  in  the  condition  of  the 
English  wage-earning  class,  taken  as  a  whole,  has  had  any 
effect  at  all  in  making  the  available  capital  of  England  less 
than  it  would  have  been  made  if  the  rise  had  not  taken 
place.  The  exceptionally  great  fall  in  the  rate  of  interest 
which  has  been  so  marked  a  feature  of  the  period,  and 
especially  of  the  last  twenty  years,  is,  in  fact,  a  slight  indica- 
tion that  the  current  is  nowadays  rather  in  the  opposite 
direction.  England  may  have  its  Trade  Unions,  its  growing 
regulation  of  private  industry,  and  its  income-tax  and  death- 
duties,  but  Germany  has  its  revolutionary  Social  Democracy, 
France  its  political  instability,  the  United  States  its  tariff 
and  currency  troubles,  India  its  famines,  Cuba  its  chronic 
rebellion,  and  South  America  its  revolutions.  One  of  the 
greatest  of  the  world's  international  financiers  lately  remarked, 
with  some  surprise,  that,  in  spite  of  the  growing  pretensions 


632  Trade  Union  Theory 

of  the  English  legislature  and  the  English  Trade  Unions  to 
interfere  with  private  enterprise,  and  to  enforce  more  liberal 
conditions  of  employment,  other  countries  were  showing  a 
positively  increasing  desire  to  remit  their  savings  for  in- 
vestment in  English  enterprises,  and  London  seemed  to  be 
becoming  more  attractive  than  ever  to  the  able  business  man. 

The  abstract  theories  of  wages  and  profits,  which  public 
opinion  once  thought  so  conclusive  against  the  Trade 
Unionist  assumptions,  are  thus  seen,  in  the  light  of  economic 
science,  to  crumble  away.  But  there  were  many  educated 
men,  especially  in  the  world  of  physical  science  and  natural 
history,  who  never  accepted  the  wire-drawn  arguments  of  the 
Wage  Fund,  but  who  nevertheless  saw,  in  the  "  principle  of 
population,"  a  biological  barrier  to  any  real  success  of  Trade 
Unionism.  Of  what  avail  could  it  be  for  combinations  of 
workmen  to  struggle  and  strive  for  higher  wages,  when  those 
higher  wages  would  only  lead  automatically  to  an  increase 
of  population,  which  must  inevitably  pull  down  things  again 
to  the  old  level?  As  one  sympathetic  friend  of  progress 
regretfully  expressed  it,  it  was  "  the  devastating  torrent  of 
children  "  that  blocked  the  way  to  any  improvement  of  the 
conditions  of  labor.1 

Now,  it  is  interesting  to  observe  that,  whereas  the 
Theory  of  the  Wage  Fund  stood  in  opposition  to  every 
kind  of  improvement  of  the  conditions  of  employment,  the 
"  principle  of  population  "  was  supposed  to  negative  only  an 
increase  in  money  wages,  or,  more  precisely,  in  the  amount 
of  food  obtained  by  the  manual  workers.  No  one  sug- 
gested that  improved  conditions  of  sanitation  in  the  factory 
had  any  tendency  to  raise  the  birth-rate  ;  and  it  would  have 
needed  a  very  fervid  Malthusianism  to  prove  that  a  shorten- 
ing of  the  hours  of  labor  resulted  in  earlier  marriages.  No 
argument  could  therefore  be  founded  on  the  "  principle  of 
population "  against  Trade  Union  efforts  to  improve  the 

1  "If  only  the  devastating  torrent  of  children  could  be  arrested  for  a  few 
years  it  would  bring  untold  relief." — J.  Cotter  Morison,  The  Service  of  Man 
(London,  1887),  preface,  p.  xxx. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  633 

conditions  of  sanitation  and  safety,  or  to  protect  the  Normal 
Day.  And  the  economists  quickly  found  reason  to  doubt 
whether  there  was  any  greater  cogency  in  the  argument 
with  regard  to  wages.  Malthus  and  Ricardo  had  habitually 
written  as  if  the  fluctuations  in  wages  meant  merely  more  or 
less  bread  to  the  laborer's  family,  and  the  public  assumed 
therefore  that  every  rise  of  wages  implied  that  more  children 
would  be  brought  up,  and  that  every  fall  would  result  in  a 
diminution.  But  the  wage-earning  population,  in  1820  as 
now,  included  any  number  of  separate  grades,  from  the 
underfed  agricultural  laborer  of  Devonshire,  whose  wages 
were  only  eight  shillings  a  week,  to  the  London  millwright 
who  refused  to  accept  a  job  under  two  guineas  a  week. 
Though  it  might  be  true  that  a  rise  in  wage  to  the  under- 
fed laborer  enabled  him  to  bring  up  more  children  to 
maturity,  and  might  even  induce  him  to  marry  at  an  earlier 
age,  it  did  not  at  all  follow  that  a  rise  of  wages  would  have 
the  same  effect  on  the  town  artisan  or  factory  operative, 
who  was  already  getting  more  than  the  bare  necessaries  of 
existence.  To  the  one  class  more  wages  meant  chiefly 
more  food  ;  to  the  other  it  meant  new  luxuries  or  additional 
amenities  of  life.  The  economists  were  quickly  convinced 
that  a  new  taste  for  luxuries  or  a  desire  for  additional 
amenities  had  a  direct  effect  in  developing  prudential 
restraint.  M'Culloch  himself  emphatically  declared,  on  this 
very  ground,  that  "  the  best  interests  of  society  require  that 
the  rate  of  wages  should  be  elevated  as  high  as  possible — 
that  a  taste  for  the  comforts,  luxuries,  and  enjoyments  of 
human  life  should  be  widely  diffused,  and,  if  possible,  inter- 
woven with  the  national  habits  and  prejudices."1  From 
the  Malthusian  point  of  view,  the  presumption  was,  as 
regards  the  artisans  and  factory  operatives,  always  in  favor 
of  a  rise  in  wages.  For  "  in  the  vast  majority  of  instances, 
before  a  rise  of  wages  can  be  counteracted  by  the  increased 
number  of  laborers  it  may  be  supposed  to  be  the  means  of 
bringing  into  the  market,  time  is  afforded  for  the  formation 

1  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  part  iii.  sec.  7. 


634  Trade  Union  Theory 

of  those  new  and  improved  tastes  and  habits,  which  are  not 
the  hasty  product  of  a  day,  a  month,  or  a  year,  but  the  late 
result  of  a  long  series  of  continuous  impressions.  After  the 
laborers  have  once  acquired  these  tastes,  population  will 
advance  in  a  slower  ratio,  as  compared  with  capital,  than 
formerly ;  and  the  laborers  will  be  disposed  rather  to  defer 
the  period  of  marriage,  than,  by  entering  on  it  prematurely, 
to  depress  their  own  condition  and  that  of  their  children." 
In  the  same  way,  the  presumption  was  strongly  against  any 
reduction  of  the  wages  of  any  classes  who  were  receiving 
more  than  bare  subsistence.  "  A  fall  of  wages,"  continues 
M'Culloch,  "has  therefore  a  precisely  opposite  effect,  and 
is,  in  most  cases,  as  injurious  to  the  laborer  as  their  rise  is 
beneficial.  In  whatever  way  wages  may  be  restored  to  their 
former  level  after  they  have  fallen,  whether  it  be  by  a  decrease 
in  the  number  of  marriages,  or  an  increase  in  the  number  of 
deaths,  or  both,  it  is  never,  except  in  ...  exceedingly  rare 
cases  .  .  .  suddenly  effected.  It  must,  generally  speaking, 
require  a  considerable  time  before  it  can  be  brought  about ; 
and  an  extreme  risk  arises  in  consequence  lest  the  tastes  and 
habits  of  the  laborers,  and  their  opinion  respecting  what  is 
necessary  for  their  comfortable  subsistence,  should  be  de- 
graded in  the  interim.  .  .  .  The  lowering  of  the  opinions  of 
the  laboring  classes,  with  respect  to  the  mode  in  which  they 
ought  to  live,  is  perhaps  the  most  serious  of  all  the  evils 
that  can  befall  them.  .  .  .  The  example  of  such  individuals, 
or  bodies  of  individuals,  as  submit  quietly  to  have  their 
wages  reduced,  and  who  are  content  if  they  get  only  the 
mere  necessaries  of  life,  ought  never  to  be  held  up  for 
public  imitation.  On  the  contrary,  everything  should  be 
done  to  make  such  apathy  be  esteemed  disgraceful."  l  There 
could  not  be  a  more  emphatic  justification  of  Trade  Union 
effort.  The  ordinary  middle-class  view  that  the  "  principle 
of  population "  rendered  nugatory  all  attempts  to  raise 
wages,  otherwise  than  in  the  slow  course  of  generations, 
was,  in  fact,  based  on  sheer  ignorance,  not  only  of  the  facts 

1  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  part  iii.  sec.  7. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  635 

of  working-class  life,  but  even  of  the  opinions  of  the  very 
economists  from  whom  it  was  supposed  to  be  derived.1  So 
far  were  the  classic  economists  from  believing  it  to  be  use- 
less to  raise  the  wages  even  of  the  laborers,  that  M'Culloch 
emphatically  declared  that  "  an  increase  of  wages  is  the  only, 
or  at  all  events  the  most  effectual  and  ready  means  by 
which  the  condition  of  the  poor  can  be  really  improved."  2 

The  modern  student  of  the  population  question  finds 
even  less  ground  for  apprehension  than  M'Culloch.  The 
general  death-rate  of  the  United  Kingdom,  like  that  of  all 
civilised  countries,  has  steadily  declined  during  the  past  half- 
century  of  sanitation,  but  no  connection  can  be  traced 
between  this  fall  and  any  rise  of  wages  ;  there  is,  indeed, 
some  slight  reason  to  believe  that  the  death-rate  has  fallen 
most  among  some  sections  of  the  wage-earners  (for  instance, 
women  of  all  ages)  and  in  some  districts  (for  instance,  the 
great  cities)  where  the  rise  in  wages  has  been  relatively  less 
than  elsewhere.  But  what  the  fanatical  Malthusian  most 
relied  on  was  the  increase  in  births.  To  him  it  seemed 
absolutely  demonstrable  that,  in  any  given  state  of  the 
working-class,  an  increase  of  wages  must  inevitably  be 
followed  by  an  increase  of  births.  That  the  number  of 

1  M'Culloch  expressly  denied  that,  on  a  rise  in  wages,  population  would 
naturally  increase  proportionately  to  the  rise,  "  as  it  is  sometimes  alleged  it  would. 
...   It  is  not  improbable  merely,  but  next  to  impossible,  that  population  should 
increase  in  the  same  proportion." — Note  VI.  to  his  edition  of  the   Wealth  of 
Nations  (London,  1839),  p.  473. 

2  J.  R.  M'Culloch,  A  Treatise  on  the  Circumstances  which  determine  the  Rate 
of  Wages  (London,  1851),  p.  49. 

Nassau  Senior  also  protested  against  the  public  view.  "Those  whose 
acquaintance  with  Political  Economy  is  superficial  (and  they  form  the  great  mass 
of  even  the  educated  classes)  have  been  misled  by  the  form  in  which  the  doctrine 
of  population  has  been  expressed.  .  .  .  Because  increased  means  of  subsistence 
may  be  followed  and  neutralised  by  a  proportionate  increase  in  the  number  of 
persons  to  be  subsisted,  they  suppose  that  such  will  necessarily  be  the  case.  .  .  . 
This  doctrine  .  .  .  furnishes  an  easy  escape  from  the  trouble  or  expense  im- 
plied by  every  project  of  improvement.  '  What  use  would  it  be  ? '  they  ask. 
' .  .  .  If  food  were  for  a  time  more  abundant,  in  a  very  short  period  the  popula- 
tion would  be  again  on  a  level  with  the  means  of  subsistence,  and  we  should  be 
just  as  ill  off  as  before.'  We  believe  these  misconceptions  to  be  extensively  pre- 
valent."— Nassau  W.  Senior,  Political  Economy,  2nd  edition,  in  Encyclopedia 
Metropolitana  (London,  1850),  p.  50. 


636  Trade  Union  Theory 

marriages  went  up  and  down  according  to  the  price  of 
wheat  was  a  universally  accepted  generalisation.  But  that 
generalisation,  whatever  may  have  been  its  truth  a  hundred 
years  ago,  has  long  ceased  to  have  any  correspondence  with 
fact.  The  marriage-rate  of  the  England  of  this  generation, 
drooping  slowly  downwards,  bears  no  assignable  relation 
either  to  the  falling  prices  of  commodities,  the  rising  wages 
of  male  labor,  or  the  growing  prosperity  of  the  country. 
What  is  more  important,  the  birth-rate  has  ceased  to  have 
any  uniform  relation  to  the  marriage-rate.  The  economists 
have  always  looked  with  longing  eyes  on  the  example  of 
France,  where  the  growth  of  population,  and  particularly  the 
number  of  births  to  a  marriage,  had,  even  when  J.  S.  Mill 
wrote  in  1848,  shown  a  steady  decline,  to  which  Mill 
attributed  much  of  the  economic  progress  of  the  peasant 
proprietors.  This  decline  in  the  birth-rate  is  now  seen  to 
be  universal  throughout  North  -  Western  Europe.  Our  own 
country  is  no  exception.  Down  to  1877,  the  birth-rate  of 
England  and  Wales  had  shown  no  sign  of  falling  off,  the  rate 
for  each  year  oscillating  about  the  mean  of  3  5  per  thousand. 
But  since  1877  the  reduction  has  been  great  and  continuous, 
the  rate  in  1895  being  only  30.4  compared  with  36.3  in 
1876,  a  fall  almost  identical  with  that  in  France  between 
1800  and  1850,  which  rilled  J.  S.  Mill  with  so  much  hope.1 
Unfortunately,  though  the  decline  in  the  English  birth- 
rate has  now  continued  for  twenty  years,  there  has  been  as 
yet  no  scientific  investigation  into  its  cause.  It  cannot  be 
ascribed  to  increased  poverty  or  privation  of  the  nation,  or 
of  the  working-class,  for,  as  compared  with  previous  times, 
there  can  be  no  doubt  that  the  incomes  of  the  English  wage- 
earners  have,  on  the  whole,  risen  ;  prices  of  commodities  have 
fallen  ;  and  the  general  prosperity  of  the  country  has  greatly 
increased.2  And  the  impression  of  statisticians  is  that  the 

1  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  Book  II.   ch.   vii.   p.    178  of  edition  of 
1865.       The  average  birth-rate  of  France   between    1801-10  and    1841-50  fell 
about  5  per  1000. 

2  For  an  estimate  of  this  progress  see  Labor  in  the  Longest  Reign,  by  Sidney 
Webb  (London,  1897). 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  637 

diminution  in  the  birth-rate  throughout  North-Western  Europe 
has  not  taken  place  among  the  poorest  sections  of  the  com- 
munity. "  After  the  researches  of  Quetelet  in  Brussels,  Farr 
in  London,  Schwabe  in  Berlin,  Villerme  and  Benoison  de 
Chateauneuf  in  Paris,  it  is  no  longer  possible  to  doubt  that 
the  maximum  of  births  takes  place  among  the  poorer  class, 
and  that  poverty  itself  is  an  irresistible  inducement  to  an 
abundant  and  disordered  birth-rate."  l  Such  facts  as  are  now 
beginning  to  be  known  point  to  the  conclusion  that  the 
fall  in  the  birth-rate  is  occurring,  not  in  those  sections  of  the 
community  which  have  barely  enough  to  live  on,  but  in  those 
which  command  some  of  the  comforts  of  life — not  in  the 
"sweated  trades,"  or  among  the  casual  laborers,  but  among 
the  factory  operatives  and  skilled  artisans.  We  can  adduce 
only  one  piece  of  statistical  evidence  in  support  of  this  hypo- 
thesis, but  that  one  piece  is,  we  think,  full  of  significance. 

The  Hearts  of  Oak  Friendly  Society  is  the  largest  cen- 
tralised Benefit  Society  in  this  country,  having  now  over  two 
hundred  thousand  adult  male  members.  No  one  is  admitted 
who  is  not  of  good  character,  and  in  receipt  of  wages  of 
twenty-four  shillings  a  week,  or  upwards.  The  membership 
consists,  therefore,  of  the  artisan  and  skilled  operative  class, 
with  some  intermixture  of  the  small  shopkeeper,  to  the 
exclusion  of  the  mere  laborer.  Among  its  provisions  is 

1  Population  and  the  Social  System,  F.  Nitti  (London,  1894),  pp.  153-162. 
Adam  Smith  had  observed  that  poverty  "seems  even  to  be  favorable  to 
generation"  (Wealth  of  Nations,  Book  I.  chap.  viii.  p.  36).  Professor  Nitti  has 
his  own  explanation  of  the  fact  :  "The  long  working  days  of  12,  14,  and  15 
hours  make  their  intellectual  improvement  impossible,  and  compel  them  to  seek 
their  sole  enjoyments  in  those  of  the  senses.  Compelled  to  work  for  many  hours 
in  places  heated  to  a  great  temperature,  often  promiscuously  with  women  ;  obliged 
to  live  upon  substances  which,  if  insufficient  for  nutrition,  frequently  cause  a  per- 
manent excitability  ;  persuaded  that  no  endeavor  will  better  their  condition,  they 
are  necessarily  impelled  to  a  great  fecundity.  Add  to  this  that  the  premature 
acceptance  of  children  in  workshops  leads  the  parents  to  believe  that  a  large 
family  is  much  rather  a  good  than  an  evil,  even  with  respect  to  family  comfort. 
...  It  is  clearly  to  be  seen  that  a  very  high  birth-rate  always  corresponds  with 
slight  wages,  long  days  of  work,  bad  food,  and  hence  a  bad  distribution  of  wealth. 
.  .  .  Nothing  is  more  certain  to  fix  limits  to  the  birth-rate  than  high  wages,  and 
the  diffusion  of  ease."  "  Poverty,"  Darwin  had  observed,  "is  not  only  a  great 
evil,  but  tends  to  its  own  increase  by  leading  to  recklessness  in  marriage." — The 
Descent  of  Man  (London,  1871),  vol.  ii.  p.  403. 


638  Trade  Union  Theory 

the  "  Lying-in  Benefit,"  a  payment  of  thirty  shillings  for  each 
confinement  of  a  member's  wife.  From  1866  to  1880  the 
proportion  of  lying-in  claims  to  membership  slowly  rose  from 
21.76  to  24.72  per  100.  From  1880  to  the  present  time  it 
has  continuously  declined,  until  it  is  now  only  between  14  and 
1 5  per  i  oo. 

The  "  devastating  torrent  of  children  "  in  this  million  of 
souls,  forming  2,\  per  cent  of  the  whole  population  of  the 
United  Kingdom,  has  accordingly  fallen  off  by  no  less  than 
two-fifths,  only  fourteen  being  born  where  formerly  twenty- 
four  would  have  seen  the  light.  The  reduction  of  the  birth-rate 
in  this  specially  thrifty  group  of  workmen's  families  has  been 
more  than  twice  the  reduction  in  the  community  as  a  whole. 
The  average  age  of  the  members  has  not  appreciably  changed, 
having  remained  throughout  between  34  and  36.  The  well- 
known  actuary  of  the  Society,  Mr.  R.  P.  Hardy,  watching 
the  statistics  year  by  year,  and  knowing  intimately  all  the 
circumstances  of  the  organisation,  attributes  this  startling 
reduction  in  the  number  of  births  of  children  to  these  speci- 
ally prosperous  and  specially  thrifty  artisans  entirely  to  their 
deliberate  desire  to  limit  the  size  of  their  families.1 

1  Our  own  impression,  based  on  ten  years'  special  investigation  into  English 
working-class  life,  coincides  with  Mr.  Hardy's  inference.  There  can  be  no  doubt 
that  the  practice  of  deliberately  taking  steps  to  limit  the  size  of  the  family  has, 
during  the  last  twenty  years,  spread  widely  among  the  factory  operatives  and 
skilled  artisans  of  Great  Britain.  We  may  remind  the  reader  that  the  Malthusian 
propaganda  of  Francis  Place  and  J.  S.  Mill  was  greatly  extended,  and  for  the 
first  time  brought  prominently  before  the  mass  of  the  people,  by  Charles  Brad- 
laugh,  M.P.,  and  Mrs.  Annie  Besant.  (In  chap.  iii.  of  his  pamphlet,  Die 
kunstliche  Beschrankung  der  Kindewahl  als  sittliche  Pflicht,  5th  edition  (Berlin, 
1897),  Dr.  Hans  Ferdy  gives  a  careful  history  of  this  movement.)  It  is  at  any 
rate  interesting  to  note  that  the  beginning  in  the  fall  of  the  birth-rate  (1877) 
coincides  closely  with  the  enormous  publicity  given  to  the  subject  by  the  prose- 
cution of  these  propagandists  in  that  very  year. 

We  attribute  this  adoption  of  neo-Malthusian  devices  to  prevent  the  burden 
of  a  large  family  (which  have,  of  course,  nothing  to  do  with  Trade  Unionism) 
chiefly  to  the  spread  of  education  among  working-class  women,  to  their  discontent 
with  a  life  of  constant  ill-health  and  domestic  worry  under  narrow  circumstances, 
and  to  the  growth  among  them  of  aspirations  for  a  fuller  and  more  independent 
existence  of  their  own.  This  change  implies,  on  the  part  of  both  husband  and 
wife,  a  large  measure  of  foresight,  deliberateness,  and  self-control,  which  is  out 
of  the  reach  of  the  less  intelligent  and  more  self-indulgent  classes,  and  difficult 
for  the  very  poor,  especially  for  the  occupants  of  one-roomed  homes. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists 


639 


Table  showing,  for  each  year  from  1866  to  1896  inclusive,  the  number 
of  Members  in  the  Hearts  of  Oak  Friendly  Society  at  the  beginning 
of  the  year,  the  number  of  those  who  received  Lying-in  Benefit 
during  the  year,  the  percentage  of  these  to  the  membership  at  the 
beginning  of  the  year,  and  the  birth-rate  per  1000  of  the  whole 
population  of  England  and  Wales.  {From  the  annual  reports  of 
the  Committee  of  Management  of  the  Hearts  of  Oak  Friendly 
Society,  and  those  of  the  Registrar-General.} 


Year. 

Hearts  of  Oak  Friendly  Society. 

England  and 
Wales:  births 
per  looo  of 
the  total 
population. 

Number  of 
Members  at  the 
beginning  of 
each  year. 

Number  of  cases 
of  Lying-in 
Benefit  paid 
during  year. 

Percentage  of 
cases  paid  to 
total  Member- 
ship at  begin- 
ning of  year. 

1866 

10,571 

2,300 

21.76 

35-2 

1867 

12,051 

2,853 

23.68 

35-4 

1868    . 

13,568 

3,075 

22.66 

35-8 

1869 

15,903 

3,509 

22.07 

34-8 

1870 

18,369 

4,173 

22.72 

35-2 

1871 

21,484 

4,685 

21.  8l 

35-0 

1872 

26,510 

6,156 

23.22 

35-6 

1873 

32,837 

7,386 

22.49 

35-4 

1874 

40,740 

9,603 

23.57 

36.0 

1875 

51,144 

12,103 

23.66 

35-4 

1876 

64,421 

15,473 

24.02 

36.3 

1877 

76,369 

18,423 

24.11 

36.0 

1878 

84,471 

20,409 

24.16 

35-6 

1879 

90,603 

22,057 

24.34 

34-7 

1880 

91,986 

22,740 

24.72 

34-2 

1881 

93,615 

21,950 

23.45 

33-9 

1882 

96,006 

2l,86o 

22.77 

33-8 

1883 

98,873 

2i,577 

21.82 

33-5 

1884 

104,239 

2i,375 

20.51 

33-6 

1885 

105,622 

21,277 

20.14 

32.9 

1886 

109,074 

21,856 

20.04 

32-8 

1887 

111,937 

20,590 

18.39 

31-9 

1888 

115,803 

20,244 

17.48 

31.2 

1889 

123,223 

20,503 

16.64 

3i.i 

1890 

131,057 

20,402 

15.57 

30.2 

1891 

141,269 

22,500 

15.93 

31-4 

1892 

153,595 

23,47i 

15.28 

30.5 

1893 

169,344 

25,430 

15.02 

30.8 

1894 

184,629 

27,000 

14.08 

29.6 

1895 

201,075 

29,263 

14.55 

30.4 

1896 

206,673 

30,313 

14.67 

640 


Trade  Union  Theory 


«3 

f°| 

0 

iri 

0 

.0 

0 

i/-i 

0 

m 

0 

in 

O 

LO 

o 

m 

0 

w 

0 

„ 

0 

w 

0 

» 

0 

M 

o 

l| 

Sil 

00 
CO 

CO 

t-> 

0 
CO 

0 
CO 

CO 

CO 

CO 

CO 

<n 

CO 

CO 

N 

CO 

Cl 

c^l 

CO 

CO 

O 

CO 

0 
CO 

?T 

OC 

/o  c 

0 

& 

r^  \ 

0 

o 

cs 

j»    O 

96^1 

t 

'-§    ° 

^ 

S 

\ 

|4 

^69  1 

^ 

X 

_ 

r^ 

7 

•ti^ 

C6Q  I 

\ 

/ 

3  § 

363  I 

</ 

/ 

x 

^ 

*  ^ 

1  6g  i 

^ 

\ 

^  l 

o6gi 

/ 

^x 

^ 

o  *K          * 

6g8i 

/ 

^ 

»"' 

o  <£          ^5 

888i 

/ 

, 

'' 

^  <§          2 

^88i 

fl 

<*' 

-"" 

t^         K 

9881 

i 

|  -g          » 

S88i 

// 

*§&           o 

^SS1 

^.*. 

/ 

^  *    df* 

^88i 

^ 

^ 

y 

^  ^       %$ 

Z88i 

f,' 

1 

*J      "1 

1881 

^^ 

-"" 

/ 

•1  '§    *2 

°88i 

' 

I 

/ 

«    ^        oZ 

'**     <o           *i  O 

6^8i 

t 

x 

^ 

VQ      Q          .    JH    S 

8^8i 

1 

i 

/ 

^  ^  |^  o  b 

^8* 

1 

7 

\O     §    ^    O    0) 

9^8i 

\ 

X 

"2  ^  ^  J  i 

S^8' 

1 

» 

y 

s?  .8  ^>  ^<S 

^^8i 

X 

s 

^•?*ljl 

e/si 

x' 

^  ^Ij-v 

z^S1 

**•» 

N 

^^   $9^ 

I/81 

3 

J 

1   ^   ^1"" 

o^8i 

~\ 

o 

\ 

v!  §  ^  JsJ 

6981 

^ 

^  ^  ^5  !* 

8981 

^ 

\ 

'1  §  1  @  (S 

^981 

-* 

-. 

\ 

•^  ^  1  1 

9981 

4 

i 

8           1 

essa 

•V0|tt^ 

O 

„, 

q 

„ 

0 

^ 

0 

i/l 

0 

0 

„ 

0 

* 

O 

LO 

0 

« 

0 

n 

0 

M 

O 

LO 

0 

«° 

'?.cs^£ 

^1- 

«* 

CO 

CO 

n 

M 

>- 

-< 

0 

0 

ON 

O 

CO 

XI 

r^ 

0 

0 

vn 

m 

-t- 

-^ 

CO 

CO 

§ 

J«§<s° 

N 

The  Verdict  of  the  Economists 


641 


We  reach  here  an  aspect  of  the  population  question  of 
which  Malthus  never  dreamt,  and  on  which  further  investiga- 
tion is  imperatively  demanded.1  There  are  many  indications 
that  the  danger  to  be  apprehended  in  North- Western  Europe 
during  the  coming  century  is  not  over-population  at  all,  but 
a  deliberate  restriction  of  population  by  the  more  prosperous, 
more  intelligent,  and  more  thrifty  sections,  brought  about  by 
the  rise  in  the  Standard  of  Life  itself.  This  is  not  the  place 
for  any  discussion  of  this  momentous  fact.  For  the  present 
we  are  concerned  only  with  the  new  light  that  it  throws  upon 
the  relation  between  the  increase  of  population  and  the  rate 
of  wages.  Instead  of  "  the  principle  of  population  "  decisively 
negativing  any  possibility  of  the  success  of  Trade  Unionism, 

1  There  are  indications  that  the  same  result  is  happening  in  New  England. 
Thus,  even  as  long  ago  as  1875,  it  was  found  that,  of  393  working-class  families 
of  Massachusetts,  those  of  the  skilled  mechanics  (earning  $800  per  annum) 
averaged  from  one  to  two  children  less  than  those  of  the  laborers  (earning  less 
than  $700  per  annum). 

Earnings  of  393  families  of  Massachusetts  in  1875,  "with  the  number  in  family r, 
averaged  by  groups  of  trades  (rearranged}. 


Trades. 

Father's 
yearly 
wages. 

Numbei 
in 
family. 

Wife 
and 
chil- 
dren 
work- 
ing. 

Total 

earnings 
of  wife 
and  chil- 
dren. 

Total 
yearly 
earnings 
of  family. 

Skilled  workshop  handicraftsmen 
Metal  workers 
Building  trades 
Teamsters     ... 
Mill  operatives 
Shoe  and  Leather  workers 

$ 
752.36 
739-30 
721.32 
630.02 
572.10 
540.00 

4| 

si 

4| 

°i 

°i 

I 
I 

$ 
69.04 
90.51 
73-oo 
105.00 

250.35 
209.00 

821.40 
829.81 
794-32 
735-02 
822.45 
749.00 

Average  of  these  six  groups 

659.18 

4* 

of 

132.82 

792.00 

Metal  workers'  laborers           . 
Workshop  laborers 
Outdoor  laborers  .... 
Mill  laborers          .... 

458.09 
433-06 
424.12 
386.04 

6| 

*i 

256.08 
232.02 

257-93 
284.08 

714.17 
665.08 
682.05 
670.12 

Average  of  these  four  groups 

425-32 

6» 

* 

257.50 

682.88 

(Sixth  Report  on  the  Statistics  of  Labour  of  Massachusetts,  1876,  p.  71.) 
VOL.  II  2  T 


642  Trade  Union  Theory 

as  is  still  often  believed  by  otherwise  well-educated  people,  the 
argument  is  all  in  the  opposite  direction.  So  far  as  we  can 
draw  any  inference  at  all  from  the  facts  of  English  life,  there 
is  no  reason  to  believe  that  a  rise  in  wages,  a  reduction  of 
hours,  or  an  improvement  of  the  conditions  of  sanitation  and 
safety  among  any  class  of  workmen,  would  cause  any  increase 
in  the  birth-rate  of  that  class  ;  and  if  the  improvement  in 
conditions  were  to  spread  to  section  after  section  of  workers 
who  are  now  below  the  level  of  the  skilled  artisan,  there  is 
every  reason  to  expect  that  it  would  result  in  a  positive 
decline  in  the  birth-rate  among  those  sections.1  To  put  the 
matter  concretely,  if  we  could,  by  Collective  Bargaining  or 
Legal  Enactment,  lift  the  London  dock-laborers  into  an 
economic  position  equal  to  that  of  the  railway  porters,  there 
would  not  only  be  no  corresponding  increase  in  the  number 
of  children  born  to  them,  but,  in  all  probability,  we  should  in 
a  very  few  years  find  an  actual  diminution  in  the  size  of  the 
average  family  of  the  class  ;  and  if  Trade  Unionism  could 
further  raise  both  them  and  the  railway  porters  to  the 

1  What  is  needed  is  a  thoroughly  scientific  investigation  of  the  subject  from 
all  sides.  First  would  come  the  statistical  inquiry  as  to  the  exact  extent  and 
distribution  of  the  decline  in  the  birth-rate.  An  analysis  of  the  registrations  of 
births  for  selected  years  would  show,  for  instance,  whether  the  birth-rate  was 
uniform  among  all  occupations,  or  varied  from  trade  to  trade ;  whether  it  bore 
any  relation  to  the  wage-levels  of  different  industries,  or  to  the  average  number 
of  rooms  occupied  by  the  families  in  these  trades,  as  tabulated  for  London  by  Mr. 
Charles  Booth  ;  or  whether  it  corresponded  with  the  degree  of  Trade  Union 
membership.  A  similar  analysis  of  births  in  the  various  friendly  societies  giving 
"  Lying-in  Benefit"  would  be  even  more  suggestive.  It  would  also  be  possible  to 
use  the  Trade  Union  and  Friendly  Society  machinery  for  taking  voluntary  censuses 
of  the  families  of  men  in  different  social  grades,  different  trades,  or  different  dis- 
tricts. Such  a  diagnosis  would  prepare  the  way  for  a  physiological  inquiry  into 
the  means  used,  and  their  physical  effects,  direct  and  indirect.  It  would  then 
be  for  the  sociologist  to  discover  the  circumstances  under  the  pressure  of  which 
these  practices  were  adopted,  and  what  effect  they  were  having  on  the  economic 
position  of  various  classes,  the  institution  of  marriage,  family  life,  and  the  great 
social  evil  of  prostitution ;  most  important  of  all,  how  sectional  restriction  of 
births  affected,  in  extent  and  character,  the  breeding  ground  of  subsequent  genera- 
tions. Some  preliminary  investigations  of  this  sort  are  being  made  by  students 
of  the  London  School  of  Economics  and  Political  Science,  but  are  stopped  for 
lack  of  funds.  We  can  imagine  no  way  of  spending  a  couple  of  thousand  pounds 
more  likely  to  be  useful  to  the  community  than  such  an  investigation.  To  us  it 
seems,  of  all  problems,  the  most  momentous  for  the  future  of  the  civilised  races. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  643 

economic   position   of   the   "  Amalgamated "    Engineer,  this 
result  would  be  still  more  certain  and  conspicuous. 

Accordingly,  we  do  not  find  any  modern  economist,  how- 
ever "  orthodox  "  may  be  his  bias,  nowadays  refuting  Trade 
Unionism  by  a  reference  either  to  the  Wage  Fund  or  to 
the  "  Population  Question."1  The  "Theory  of  Distribution  " 
which  to-day  holds  the  field  is  of  very  different  character, 
and  one  from  which  the  opponent  of  Trade  Unionism  can 
derive  little  comfort.  To  begin  with,  it  is  declared  that  wages, 
like  other  incomes,  depend  upon  the  amount  of  the  aggregate 
revenue  of  a  community,  not  upon  the  amount  of  its  capital. 
"  The  labour  and  capital  of  the  country,"  says  Professor 
Marshall,  "  acting  on  its  natural  resources,  produce  annually 
a  certain  net  aggregate  of  commodities,  material  and  im- 
material, including  services  of  all  kinds.  This  is  the  true 
net  annual  income  or  revenue  of  the  country ;  or  the 
National  Dividend  ...  it  is  divided  up  into  Earnings 
of  Labor,  Interest  of  Capital,  and  lastly  the  Producer's 
Surplus,  or  Rent,  of  land,  and  of  other  differential  advan- 
tages for  production.  It  constitutes  the  whole  of  them, 
and  the  whole  of  it  is  distributed  among  them  ;  and  the 
larger  it  is,  the  larger,  other  things  being  equal,  will  be  the 
share  of  each  agent  of  production."  The  extent  and  character 
of  the  industries  of  the  community,  and  the  ever-changing 
level  of  wages  and  prices,  are  determined  by  the  perpetual 
play  of  Supply  and  Demand,  acting  through  the  "  law  of 
substitution."  "  The  production  of  everything,  whether  an 
agent  of  production  or  a  commodity  ready  for  immediate 
consumption,  is  carried  forward  up  to  that  limit  or  margin 
at  which  there  is  equilibrium  between  the  forces  of  demand 
and  supply.  The  amount  of  the  thing,  and  its  price,  the 
amounts  of  the  several  factors  or  agents  of  production  used 
in  making  it,  and  their  prices — all  these  elements  mutually 

1  Thus,  Professor  Marshall,  though  he  elsewhere  uses  expressions  which 
retain  traces  of  the  older  view,  observes,  in  the  latest  edition  of  his  Principles  of 
Economics  (London,  1895),  as  corrected  by  the  fly-leaf,  "it  is  indeed  true  that 
a  permanent  rise  of  prosperity  is  quite  as  likely  to  lower  as  to  raise  the  birth- 
rate "  (p.  594). 


644  Trade  Union  Theory 

determine  one  another,  and  if  an  external  cause  should  alter 
any  one  of  them,  the  effect  of  the  disturbance  extends  to  all 
the  others."  And  the  Rent,  it  will  be  seen,  "  is  the  excess 
value  of  the  return  which  can  be  got  by  its  aid  where  labor 
and  capital  are  applied  with  normal  ability  up  to  the  margin 
of  profitableness  over  that  which  the  same  labor,  capital,  and 
ability  would  get  if  working  without  the  aid  of  any  such 
advantage."  Nor  is  this  confined  to  land  rent  (or  to  "  a 
differential  advantage  not  made  by  man  "),  for  we  are  else- 
where told  "  that  the  rent  of  land  is  no  unique  fact,  but 
simply  the  chief  species  of  a  large  genus  of  economic  pheno- 
mena ;  and  that  the  theory  of  the  rent  of  land  is  no  isolated 
economic  doctrine,  but  merely  one  of  the  chief  applications 
of  a  particular  corollary  from  the  general  theory  of  demand 
and  supply  ;  and  that  there  is  a  continuous  gradation  from 
the  true  rent  of  those  free  gifts  which  have  been  appropriated 
by  man,  through  the  income  derived  from  permanent  im- 
provements of  the  soil,  to  those  yielded  by  farm  and  factory 
buildings,  steam  engines,  and  less  durable  goods."  The 
result  is  a  constant  tendency  to  equality,  but  only  to  equality 
of  remuneration  for  the  marginal  use.  "  Other  things  being 
equal,  the  larger  the  supply  of  any  agent  of  production,  the 
further  will  it  have  to  push  its  way  into  uses  for  which  it  is 
not  specially  fitted,  and  the  lower  will  be  the  demand  price 
with  which  it  will  have  to  be  contented  in  those  uses  in 
which  its  employment  is  on  the  verge  or  margin  of  not  being 
found  profitable,  and,  in  so  far  as  completion  equalises  the 
price  which  it  gets  in  all  uses,  this  price  will  be  its  price  for 
all  uses."  l 

Thus,  the  effect  of  perfectly  free  and  unrestrained  in- 
dividual competition  among  laborers  and  capitalists  is,  on 
the  one  hand,  to  secure  to  their  owners  the  entire  differential 
advantage  of  all  those  factors  of  production  which  are  better 
than  the  worst  in  normal  use,  and,  on  the  other,  to  reduce 
the  personal  remuneration  for  all  the  members  of  each  class 

1  Principles  of  Economic s>  by  Professor  Alfred  Marshall,  3rd  edition  (London, 
1895),  Book  VI.  chap.  i.  pp.  588,  591,  609,  and  chap.  ix.  p.  705. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  645 

of  producers  to  the  level  of  the  last,  and  least  advantageously 
situated,  member  of  that  class  for  the  time  being.  The 
modern  economist  tells  each  class  of  producers  plainly  what 
will  happen  to  their  incomes  if  there  is  no  interference  with 
free  competition.  The  total  net  produce  of  the  class  may 
be  considerable ;  the  total  utility  and  value  of  the  services  of 
the  class  as  a  whole  to  the  employers  may  be  immense ;  the 
consumers  themselves  may  be  willing,  rather  than  forego  the 
commodity,  to  pay  a  higher  price.  Nevertheless,  if  the  work- 
men in  that  particular  class  compete  freely  among  them- 
selves for  employment,  and  the  employers  are  unrestrained  in 
taking  advantage  of  this  "  Perfect  Competition,"  the  price  with 
which  all  the  members  of  the  class  will  have  to  be  content 
will  be  set  by  the  last  additional  workman  in  the  class  whose 
"  employment  is  on  the  verge  or  margin  of  not  being  found 
profitable."  Under  Perfect  Competition,  "  the  wages  of  every 
class  of  labor  tend  to  be  equal  to  the  produce  due  to  the 
additional  labor  of  the  marginal  laborer  of  that  class."  l 

But  what  the  isolated  individual  wage-earner  thus  fore- 
goes, the  employer  does  not  necessarily  gain.  For  the  same 
reasoning  applies,  as  Professor  Marshall  points  out,  to  capital 
in  all  its  mobile  forms.  The  demand -price  is  determined, 
not  by  the  total  utility  of  the  advantages  to  be  gained  by 
the  use  of  each  unit  of  capital,  but  by  the  utility  of  the  last 
unit  of  mobile  capital,  "  in  those  uses  in  which  its  employment 
is  on  the  verge  or  margin  of  not  being  found  profitable." 
Competition  among  capitalists  will  force  them  to  cede  to  the 
consumer  anything  above  the  net  advantages  of  the  last,  or 
marginal,  unit  of  mobile  capital.  Thus,  under  Perfect  Com- 
petition, it  is  on  the  one  hand  the  landlord,  or  other  owner 
of  the  rents  or  "  quasi-rents  "  of  superior  instruments  of  pro- 
duction, and  on  the  other  the  consumer,  in  proportion  to  the 
extent  of  his  consumption,  who  is  always  getting  the  benefit 
of  that  "  law  of  substitution  "  which  pares  down  the  incomes 
of  laborers  and  capitalists  alike,  whenever  these,  in  particular 

1  Principles  of  Economics,  by  Professor  Alfred  Marshall,  3rd  edition  (London, 
1895),  Book  VI.  chap.  i.  p.   584. 


646  Trade  Union  Theory 

instances,  rise  above  the  level  for  the  time  being  of  the 
equivalent  of  the  marginal  use.1 

All  that  abstract  economics  can  nowadays  tell  us  about 
the  normal  rate  of  wages  is,  therefore,  that  under  perfectly 
free  competition  it  will  be  always  'tending,  for  each  distinct 
and  fairly  homogeneous  class  of  workman,  to  be  no  more 
than  can  be  got  by  "the  marginal  man"  of  that  class,  and  in 
so  far  as  labor  may  be  regarded  as  freely  mobile  between 
the  different  grades,  no  more  than  would  be  given  for  the 
"  marginal  man  "  of  the  community  as  a  whole.  How  much 
that  will  be  cannot,  even  on  the  assumption  of  perfect  com- 
pletion and  frictionless  mobility,  be  determined  by  any 
reasoning  of  abstract  economics.  "  It  appears,  then,  as  the 
conclusion  of  the  argument,"  sums  up  our  latest  systematic 
writer,  "  that  there  is  no  short  and  simple  rule  by  which  the 
normal  rate  of  wages  in  any  employment  can  be  deter- 
mined over  a  long  period  or  in  the  long  run.  We  cannot 
assign  with  any  degree  of  precision  the  superior  and  the 
inferior  limits  between  which  it  must  lie,  and  thus  we  cannot 
fix  upon  any  point  about  which  the  market  rates  must 
oscillate."2 

This  necessary  indeterminateness  of  the  wage-contract, 
even  under  perfect  competition,  was  insisted  on  by  Thornton 
in  1869,  and  was  thereupon  mathematically  demonstrated. 

1  This  Theory  of  Distribution  would  gain  in  logical  completeness  if,  after  the 
manner  of  the  classic  economists,  (i)  we  could  assume  that  this  equivalent  of  the 
advantage  of  the  marginal  use  of  capital  itself  precisely  determined,  in  any  com- 
munity, how  much  capital  would  be  saved  and  productively  employed — the  rate 
of  accumulation  being  so  affected  by  every  variation  from  the  "normal  "  rate  of 
interest  as  eventually  to  counteract  the  variation ;  and  if  (2)  we  might  believe 
that  the  amount  of  the  net  produce  of  the  marginal  laborer  determined  how  many 
laborers  would  exist — the  increase  of  population  varying  in  exact  correspond- 
ence with  these  "normal"  wages.      But  as  -we  do  not  know  whether,   human 
nature  being  as  it  is,  a  rise  in  the  rate  of  interest  would  on  the  whole  augment 
the  amount   of  productive  capital  or   decrease  it ;    or  whether  a  rise  in  wages 
would  increase  the  birth-rate  or  diminish  it,  both   the  amount  of  capital  and 
the  number  of  the  population  must,  as  far  as  abstract  economics  is  concerned, 
for  the  present  be  treated  as  indeterminate  ;  or,  rather,  as  data  which,  for  any 
particular  time  and  country,   the  abstract  economist  can  only  accept  from  the 
statistician. 

2  J.  S.  Nicholson,  Principles  of  Political  Economy  (Edinburgh,  1893),  p.  353. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  647 

In  a  comparatively  unnoticed  paper,  Fleeming  Jenkin,  a 
physicist  of  rare  power,  showed  the  economists  of  1870 
that,  on  their  own  reasoning,  it  followed  that  the  rate  of 
wages  would  vary  according  as  the  wage-earners  took  steps 
for  their  own  protection  or  not.  In  flat  contradiction  of  the 
current  middle-class  opinion,  he  concluded  that  the  case  of 
"  the  laborer  who  does  not  bargain  as  to  his  wages  ...  is 
the  case  of  a  forced  sale,  as  at  a  bankruptcy,  and  of  any 
other  sale  by  auction  without  a  reserved  price.  .  .  .  The 
knowledge  that  goods  must  be  sold,  that,  in  fact,  there  is  no 
reserved  price  ...  at  once  lowers  the  demand  curve  while 
it  raises  the  supply,  and  by  a  double  action  lowers  the 
price.  .  .  .  Both  in  a  given  market  and  on  an  average  of 
years,  the  power  of  bargaining  will  enable  a  seller  to  obtain 
higher  prices  [than  without  that  power]."  l 

The  whole  subject  was  minutely  investigated  in  1881 
by  Professor  F.  Y.  Edgeworth,  from  the  mathematical  stand- 
point, in  a  work  which  has  received  too  little  attention. 
He  sums  up  his  argument  as  follows.  "  Suppose  a  market 
consisting  of  an  equal  number  of  masters  and  servants, 
offering  respectively  wages  and  service,  subject  to  the 
condition  that  no  man  can  serve  two  masters,  no  master 
employ  more  than  one  man  ;  or  suppose  equilibrium  already 
established  between  such  parties  to  be  disturbed  by  any 
sudden  influx  of  wealth  into  the  hands  of  the  masters.  Then 
there  is  no  determinate,  and  very  generally  [no]  unique 
arrangement  towards  which  the  system  tends  under  the 
operation  of,  may  we  say,  a  law  of  Nature,  and  which  would 
be  predictable  if  we  knew  beforehand  the  real  requirements 
of  each,  or  of  the  average  dealer ;  but  there  are  an  indefinite 
number  of  arrangements  a  priori  possible,  towards  one  of 
which  the  system  is  urged,  not  by  the  concurrence  of 
innumerable  (as  it  were)  neuter  atoms  eliminating  chance, 
but  (abstraction  being  made  of  custom)  by  what  has  been 
called  the  Art  of  Bargaining — higgling  dodges  and  designing 

1   "  Graphic  Representation  of  the  Laws  of  Supply  and  Demand,"  by  Fleeming 
Jenkin,  in  Recess  Studies  (Edinburgh,  1870),  pp.  173,  175. 


648  Trade  Union  Theory 

obstinacy,    and    other    incalculable    and    often    disreputable 
accidents."  l 

But  competition  between  individual  producers  and  con- 
sumers, laborers  and  capitalists,  is,  as  the  economist  is  now 
careful  to  explain,  in  actual  life  very  far  from  perfect,  and 
shows  no  tendency  to  become  so.2  Combination,  we  are 
told,3  "  is  as  much  a  normal  condition  of  modern  industry  " 
as  competition,  as,  indeed,  on  the  doctrine  of  freedom  of 
contract  it  is  bound  to  be.  When  wage-earners  combine 
to  improve  the  conditions  of  their  employment,  or  when 
employers,  on  the  other  hand,  tacitly  or  formally  unite  to 
reduce  wages, — when,  again,  a  great  capitalist  undertaking 
enjoys  a  virtual  monopoly  of  any  kind  of  employment, 
abstract  economics  is  frankly  incapable  of  predicting  the 
result.  "  If,"  says  Professor  Marshall,  "  the  employers  in 
any  trade  act  together  and  so  do  the  employed,  the  solution 
of  the  problem  of  wages  becomes  indeterminate.  The  trade 
as  a  whole  may  be  regarded  as  receiving  a  surplus  (or  quasi- 
rent)  consisting  of  the  excess  of  the  aggregate  price  which  it 
can  get  for  such  wares  as  it  produces,  over  what  it  has  to 
pay  to  other  trades  for  the  raw  materials,  etc.,  which  it  buys  ; 
and  there  is  nothing  but  bargaining  to  decide  the  exact  shares 
in  which  this  should  go  to  employers  and  employed.  No 
lowering  of  wages  will  be  permanently  in  the  interest  of 
employers  which  is  unnecessary  and  drives  many  skilled 
workers  to  other  markets,  or  even  to  other  industries  in 
which  they  abandon  the  special  income  derived  from  their 
particular  skill ;  and  wages  must  be  high  enough  in  an 
average  year  to  attract  young  people  to  the  trade.  This 

1  Mathematical  Psychics  (London,  1881),  p.  46,  by  F.  Y.  Edgeworth,  now 
Drummond  Professor  of  Political  Economy  in  the  University  of  Oxford. 

2  "  In  practical  life   such  frictional  disturbances  are  innumerable.       At  no 
moment  and  in  no  branch  of  production  are  they  entirely  absent.     And  thus  it  is 
that  the  Law  of  Costs  is  recognised  as  a  law  that  is  only  approximately  valid  ;  a 
law  riddled  through  and  through  with  exceptions.     These  innumerable  exceptions, 
small  and  great,  are  the  inexhaustible  source  of  the  undertaker's  profits,  but  also 
of  the  undertaker's  losses."—  The  Positive  Theory  of  Capital,  by  E.  v.  Bohm- 
Bavverk,  translated  by  W.  Smart  (London,  1891),  p.  234. 

3  Stitdies  in  Economics,  by  W.    Smart,   Adam  Smith  Professor  of  Political 
Economy  in  the  University  of  Glasgow  (London,  1895),  P-  259- 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  649 

sets  lower  limits  to  wages,  and  upper  limits  are  set  by 
corresponding  necessities  as  to  the  supply  of  capital  and 
business  power.  But  what  point  within  these  limits  should 
be  taken  at  any  time  can  be  decided  only  by  higgling  and 
bargaining? * 

We  thus  see  that  it  is  not  only  economically  permissible, 
but  in  the  view  of  our  best  authorities  necessary  for  self-pro- 
tection, that  the  workmen  should  not  simply  acquiesce  in  what- 
ever conditions  the  employer  may  propose,  but  that  they 
should  take  deliberate  steps  to  protect  themselves  by  "  higgling 
and  bargaining,"  if  they  are  not  to  suffer  lower  wages  and 
worse  conditions  of  employment  than  there  is  any  economic 
necessity  for.  "  If  the  workman,"  says  Walker,  "  from  any 
cause  does  not  pursue  his  interest  he  loses  his  interest^  whether 
he  refrain  from  bodily  fear,  from  poverty,  from  ignorance, 
from  timidity,  and  dread  of  censure,  or  from  the  effects  of 
bad  political  economy  which  assures  him  that  if  he  does  not 
seek  his  interest,  his  interest  will  seek  him." 2  And  if  the 
workmen  ask  how  they  can  strengthen  themselves  in  this 
higgling  and  bargaining,  how  they  are  most  effectually  to 
pursue  their  own  interest,  the  answer  of  abstract  economics 
is  now,  positively,  combination.  "  In  that  contest  of  endurance 
between  buyer  and  seller  [of  labor],"  wrote  J.  S.  Mill  in  1869, 
"  nothing  but  a  close  combination  among  the  employed  can 
give  them  even  a  chance  of  successfully  competing  against 
the  employers." 3  This  was  one  of  the  conclusions  that  most 
shocked  Mill's  economic  friends  of  1869,  but  it  is  one  which 
has  since  become  an  economic  commonplace.4  In  1881 

1  Elements  of  Economics  of  Industry,  by  Professor  A.  Marshall  (London,  1892), 
p.  341.      "Demand  and  supply  are  not  physical  agencies  which  thrust  a  given 
amount  of  wages  into  the  laborer's  hand  without  the  participation  of  his  own  will 
and  actions.    The  market  rate  is  not  fixed  for  him  by  some  self-acting  instrument, 
but  is  the  result  of  bargaining  between  human  beings — of  what  Adam  Smith  calls 
'the  higgling  of  the  market.'" — J.    S.    Mill,   Principles  of  Political  Economy, 
Book  V.  ch.  x.  sec.  5. 

2  The  Wages  Question,  by  F.  A.  Walker  (New  York,  1876  ;  London,  1891), 
pp.  364,  411. 

3  Fortnightly  Reviciv,   May   1869;   Dissertations  and  Disciissions  (London, 
1876),  vol.  iv.  p.  42. 

4  "  Combination  is,  in  fact,  the  only  way  by  which  the  poor  can  place  them- 


650  Trade  Union  Theory 

Professor  Edgeworth,  in  the  work  which  we  have  already 
quoted,  placed  it  on  the  rock  of  mathematical  analysis. 
Summing  up  a  long  mathematical  argument  as  to  "  the 
general  case  in  which  numbers,  natures,  and  combinations 
are  unequal,"  he  declares  that  "combination  tends  to 
introduce  or  increase  indeterminateness  ;  and  the  final  settle- 
ments thereby  added  are  more  favorable  to  the  combiners 
than  the  (determinate  or  indeterminate)  final  settlements 
previously  existing."  In  his  opinion,  in  fact,  "the  one  thing 
from  an  abstract  point  of  view  visible  amidst  the  jumble 
of  catallactic  molecules,  the  jostle  of  competitive  crowds,  is 
that  those  who  form  themselves  into  compact  bodies  by 
combination  do  not  tend  to  lose,  but  stand  to  gain"  *  Nor 
need  the  combination  amount  in  any  sense  to  a  monopoly. 
"  If,  for  instance,"  proceeds  Professor  Edgeworth,  "  powerful 
trade  unions  did  not  seek  to  fix  the  quid  pro  quo,  the 
amounts  of  labor  exchanged  for  wealth  (which  they  would 
be  quite  competent  to  seek),  but  only  the  rate  of  exchange, 
it  being  left  to  each  capitalist  to  purchase  as  much  labor  as 
he  might  demand  at  that  rate,  there  would  still  be  that  sort 
of  indeterminateness  favorable  to  unionists  above  described." 
And  no  trade  need  refrain,  out  of  consideration  for  the 
interests  of  other  trades,  from  doing  the  best  it  can  for  itself 
in  its  negotiations  with  its  own  particular  employers.  "  It  is 
safe  to  say,"  observes  Professor  Taussig,  "  that  in  concrete  life 
it  happens  very  rarely,  probably  never,  that  a  specific  rise  in 
wages,  secured  by  strike  or  trade  union  pressure  or  simple 
agreement,  can  be  shown  to  bring  any  off-setting  loss  in  the 
wages  of  those  not  directly  concerned.  .  .  .  The  chances  are 
against  any  traceable  loss  which  would  off-set  the  visible  gain. 
Certainly  an  unbiassed  and  judicious  adviser,  having  the 
interest  of  all  laborers  at  heart,  would  hesitate  long  before 
counselling  any  particular  set  of  laborers  against  an  endeavor 

selves  on  a  par  with  the  rich  in  bargaining." — H.  Sidgwick,  Elements  of  Politics, 
ch.  xxviii.  sec.  2,  p.  579  of  2nd  edition  (London,  1897). 

1  Mathematical  Psychics  (London,   1881),  by  Prof.   F.   Y.    Edgeworth,  pp. 
43.  44- 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  651 

to  get  better  terms  from  their  employers,  on  the  ground  that 
as  an  ulterior  result  of  success  some  of  their  fellows  might 
suffer.  If  no  other  objection  than  this  presented  itself,  he 
could  safely  assert  that  economic  science  had  nothing  to  say 
against  their  endeavors,  and  much  in  favor  of  them."  1  Pro- 
fessor Sidgwick  has  therefore  no  difficulty  in  reciting  various 
typical  circumstances  under  which  abstract  economics  show 
it  to  be  quite  possible  for  Trade  Unions  to  raise  wages,  and 
in  concluding  that  "  in  all  the  above  cases  it  is  possible  for  a 
combination  of  workmen  to  secure,  either  temporarily  or 
permanently,  a  rise  in  wages  ;  whilst  in  none  of  them,  except 
the  last,  has  such  gain  any  manifest  tendency  to  be  counter- 
balanced by  future  loss.  And  it  does  not  appear  that  these 
cases  are  in  practice  very  exceptional,  or  that  the  proposition 
that  *  Trade  Unions  cannot  in  the  long  run  succeed  in  raising 
wages '  corresponds  even  approximately  to  the  actual  facts 
of  industry,"  whilst  there  is  really  no  ground  for  the  conclusion 
of  the  older  economists  "  that  if  one  set  of  laborers  obtain  an 
increase  of  wages  in  this  way,  there  must  be  a  corresponding 
reduction  in  the  wages  of  other  laborers."  2  Finally,  we  have 
the  deliberate  judgment  of  Professor  Marshall,  cautiously 
summing  up  his  examination  of  the  arguments  for  and 
against  Trade  Unionism.  "  In  trades  which  have  any  sort 
of  monopoly  the  workers,  by  limiting  their  numbers,  may 
secure  very  high  wages  at  the  expense  partly  of  the  employers, 
but  chiefly  of  the  general  community.  But  such  action 
generally  diminishes  the  number  of  skilled  workers,  and  in 
this  and  other  ways  takes  more  in  the  aggregate  from  the 
real  wages  of  workers  outside  than  it  adds  to  those  of 
workers  inside  ;  and  thus  on  the  balance  it  lowers  average 
wages.3  .  .  .  Passing  from  selfish  and  exclusive  action  of  this 

1  Wages  and  Capital:  an  Examination  of  the   Wages  Fund  Doctrine,   by 
F.  W.  Taussig,  Professor  of  Political  Economy  in  Harvard  University  (London, 
1896),  pp.  103,  104. 

2  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  by  Henry  Sidgwick,   Professor  of  Moral 
Philosophy  at  the  University  of  Cambridge  (London,   1883),  p.  363. 

3  Other  authorities  doubt  whether,  on  any  reasoning  of  abstract  economics, 
this  drawback  can  be  shown  necessarily  to  result.       "If,"   observes    Professor 
Edgeworth,  "it  is  attempted  to  enforce  the  argument  against  Trade  Unionism  by 


652  Trade  Union  Theory 

sort,  we  find  that  unions  generally  can  so  arrange  their 
bargaining  with  employers  as  to  remove  the  special  disad- 
vantages under  which  workmen  would  lie  if  bargaining  as  indi- 
viduals and  without  reserve ;  and  in  consequence  employers 
may  sometimes  find  the  path  of  least  resistance  in  paying 
somewhat  higher  wages  than  they  would  otherwise  have 
done.  In  trades  which  use  much  fixed  capital  a  strong  union 
may  for  a  time  divert  a  great  part  of  the  aggregate  net  income 
(which  is  really  a  quasi-rent)  to  the  workers  ;  but  this  injury 
to  capital  will  be  partly  transmitted  to  consumers,  and  partly, 
by  its  rebound,  reduce  employment  and  lower  wages.  .  .  . 
Other  things  being  equal,  the  presence  of  a  union  in  a  trade 
raises  wages  relatively  to  other  trades.  But  the  influence 
which  unions  exert  on  the  average  level  of  wages  is  less  than 
would  be  inferred  by  looking  at  the  influence  which  they 
exert  in  each  particular  trade.  When  the  measures  which 
they  take  to  raise  wages  in  one  trade  have  the  effect  of 
rendering  business  more  difficult,  or  anxious,  or  impeding  it 
in  any  other  way,  they  are  likely  to  diminish  employment  in 
other  trades,  and  thus  to  cause  a  greater  aggregate  loss  of  wages 
to  other  trades  than  they  gain  for  themselves,  and  to  lower 
and  not  raise  the  average  level  of  wages.  .  .  .  The  power  of 
unions  to  raise  general  wages  by  direct  means  is  never  great ; 
it  is  never  sufficient  to  contend  successfully  with  the  general 
economic  forces  of  the  age,  when  their  drift  is  against  a  rise 
of  wages.  But  yet  it  is  sufficient  materially  to  benefit  the 
worker,  when  it  is  so  directed  as  to  co-operate  with  and  to 
strengthen  those  general  agencies,  which  are  tending  to 
improve  his  position  morally  and  economically." l  No 

the  consideration  that  it  tends  to  diminish  the  total  national  produce,  the  obvious 
reply  is  that  Unionists,  as  'Economic  men,'  are  not  concerned  with  the  total 
produce.  Because  the  total  produce  is  diminished  it  does  not  follow  that  the 
laborer's  share  is  diminished  (the  loss  may  fall  on  the  capitalist  and  the 
entrepreneur  whose  compressibility  has  been  well  shown  by  Mr.  Sidgwick, 
Fortnightly  Review,  September  1879) ;  much  less  does  it  follow  that  there  should 
be  diminished  that  quantity  which  alone  the  rational  unionist  is  concerned  to 
increase — the  laborer's  utility." — Mathematical  Psychics,  p.  45. 

1  Elements  of  Economics  of  Industry,  by  Prof.  A.  Marshall  (London,  1892), 
pp.  407,  408. 


The  Verdict  of  the  Economists  653 

economist  of  the  present  day  can  therefore  look  forward,  as 
the  popular  advisers  of  the  middle  class  even  within  the 
present  generation  confidently  could,  to  a  time  when  "  the 
fanatical  faith  of  the  working  classes  in  the  artificial 
mechanism  of  combination  will  give  place  to  trust  in  the 
wiser,  because  more  natural,  system  of  individual  competition ; 
and  the  hiring  of  labor,  like  the  exchange  of  commodities, 
will  be  set  free,  to  be  regulated  by  the  Heaven-ordained  laws 
of  Supply  and  Demand." l 

Thus,  economic  authority  to-day,  looking  back  on  the 
confident  assertions  against  Trade  Unionism  made  by 
M'Culloch  and  Mill,  Nassau  Senior  and  Harriet  Martineau, 
Fawcett  and  Cairnes,  has  humbly  to  admit,  in  the  words  of 
the  present  occupant  of  the  chair  once  rilled  by  Nassau  Senior 
himself,  that  "  in  the  matter  of  [Trade]  Unionism,  as  well  as 
in  that  of  the  predeterminate  wage-fund,  the  untutored  mind 
of  the  workman  had  gone  more  straight  to  the  point  than 
economic  intelligence  misled  by  a  bad  method." 2  The 
verdict  of  abstract  economics  is,  in  fact,  decidedly  in  favor 
of  the  Trade  Union  contention,  if  only  within  certain  limits. 
Whether  this  view  of  Trade  Unionism  in  the  abstract  is 
worth  any  more,  in  relation  to  the  actual  problems  of 
practical  life,  than  the  contrary  verdict  arrived  at  by  the 
economists  of  a  preceding  generation,  is  a  matter  on  which 
opinions  will  differ.  For  our  own  part,  we  are  loth  to  pin  our 
faith  to  any  manipulation  of  economic  abstractions,  with  or 
without  the  aid  of  mathematics.  We  are  inclined  to  attach 
more  weight  to  a  consideration  of  the  processes  of  industrial 
life  as  they  actually  exist.  In  the  next  chapter  we  shall 
accordingly  seek  to  follow  out  the  course  of  that  "  higgling 
and  bargaining  "  upon  which,  as  we  have  seen,  the  conditions 
of  employment  admittedly  depend. 

1   Trade  Unionism,  by  James  Stirling,  p.  55. 
*  Mathematical  Psychics  (p.  45),  by  F.  Y.  Edgeworth. 


CHAPTER    II 

THE    HIGGLING    OF    THE    MARKET 

IT  is  often  taken  for  granted  that  the  higgling  of  the 
market,  in  which  the  workman  is  interested,  is  confined  to 
the  negotiation  between  himself  and  his  employer.  But  the 
share  of  the  aggregate  product  of  the  nation's  industry  which 
falls  to  the  wage-earners  as  a  class,  or  to  any  particular 
operative — notably  the  division  of  that  portion  which  may 
be  regarded  as  the  "  debatable  land  " — depends  not  merely 
on  the  strength  or  weakness  of  the  workman's  position 
towards  the  capitalist  employer,  but  also  on  the  strategic 
position  of  the  employer  towards  the  wholesale  trader,  that 
of  the  wholesale  trader  towards  the  shopkeeper,  and  that  of 
the  shopkeeper  towards  the  consumer.  The  higgling  of  the 
market,  which,  under  a  system  of  free  competition  and  Indi- 
vidual Bargaining,  determines  the  conditions  of  employment, 
occurs  in  a  chain  of  bargains  linking  together  the  manual 
worker,  the  capitalist  employer,  the  wholesale  trader,  the 
shopkeeper,  and  the  customer.  Any  addition  to,  or  sub- 
traction from,  this  series  of  intermediaries  between  the 
manual  worker  and  the  consumer — the  excision  of  the 
capitalist  employer  or  of  the  wholesale  or  retail  trader,  the 
insertion  of  a  sub-contractor  at  one  end  or  of  a  "  tallyman  " 

1  The  "tallyman"  is  a  drapery  hawker,  visiting  the  houses  of  his  customers, 
and  selling  his  wares  upon  a  particularly  objectionable  system  of  credit.  See 
the  article  on  "Tally  System  "in  Chambers's  Encyclopedia  (London,  1874)  ; 
and  the  excellent  article  under  "Tally  Trade"  in  M'Culloch's  Dictionary  of 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  655 

at  the  other — will  be  found,  in  practice,  to  materially  alter 
the  position  of  all  the  parties.  We  must  therefore  examine 
separately  the  conditions  of  each  of  these  series  of  bargains.1 

It  will  be  convenient  to  put  on  one  side  for  the  moment 
any  consideration  of  gluts  or  scarcities — whether  there  is  a 
surplus  of  workmen  seeking  situations  or  of  vacancies  to  be 
filled  ;  whether  manufacturers  are  heaping  up  stocks,  or  are 
unable  to  keep  pace  with  the  orders  they  receive  ;  whether 
the  trader's  "turn-over"  is  falling  off  or  rapidly  increasing. 
These  variations  in  supply  and  demand  will,  of  course, 
greatly  affect  the  relative  pressure  of  the  forces  which  deter- 
mine particular  bargains.  But  fluctuations  of  this  kind, 
however  important  they  may  be  to  the  parties  concerned, 
and  however  much  we  may  believe  them,  in  the  long  run,  to 
weight  the  scales  in  favor  of  one  class  or  another,  tend  only 
to  obscure  the  essential  and  permanent  characteristics  of  the 
several  relationships.  To  reveal  these  characteristics,  we 
must  assume  a  market  in  a  state  of  perfect  equilibrium, 
where  the  supply  is  exactly  equal  in  quantity  to  the 
demand. 

We  begin  with  the  bargain  between  the  workman  and 
the  capitalist  employer.  We  assume  that  there  is  only  a 
single  situation  vacant  and  only  one  candidate  for  it.  When 
the  workman  applies  for  the  post  to  the  employer's  foreman, 
the  two  parties  to  the  bargain  differ  considerably  in  strategic 
strength.  There  is  first  the  difference  of  alternative.  If  the 
foreman,  and  the  capitalist  employer  for  whom  he  acts,  fail 
to  come  to  terms  with  the  workman,  they  may  be  put  to 
some  inconvenience  in  arranging  the  work  of  the  establish- 

Commerce  and  Commercial  Navigation  (London,  1882),  pp.  1357-58  ;  also  C.  S. 
Devas's  Groundwork  of  Economics  (London,  1883),  note  to  sec.  213,  p.  443. 

1  It  is,  in  our  view,  one  of  the  most  unsatisfactory  features  of  the  older 
economists,  that  they  habitually  ignored  the  actual  structure  of  the  industrial 
world  around  them,  and  usually  confined  their  analysis  to  the  abstract  figures  of 
"  the  capitalist "  and  "  the  laborer."  For  a  brief  description  of  the  main  outline 
of  English  business  structure  see  the  article  on  "  The  House  of  Lords  and  the 
Sweating  System,"  Nineteenth  Century ',  May  1890,  by  Beatrice  Potter  (Mrs. 
Sidney  Webb).  A  systematic  economic  analysis  of  the  actual  mechanism  of 
English  business  life  is  badly  needed. 


656  Trade  Union  Theory 

ment.  They  may  have  to  persuade  the  other  workmen  to 
work  harder  or  to  work  overtime  ;  they  may  even  be  com- 
pelled to  leave  a  machine  vacant,  and  thus  run  the  risk  of 
some  delay  in  the  completion  of  an  order.  Even  if  the 
workman  remains  obdurate,  the  worst  that  the  capitalist 
suffers  is  a  fractional  decrease  of  the  year's  profit.1  Mean- 
while, he  and  his  foreman,  with  their  wives  and  families,  find 
their  housekeeping  quite  unaffected  ;  they  go  on  eating  and 
drinking,  working  and  enjoying  themselves,  whether  the 
bargain  with  the  individual  workman  has  been  made  or  not. 
Very  different  is  the  case  with  the  wage-earner.  If  he 
refuses  the  foreman's  terms  even  for  a  day,  he  irrevocably 
loses  his  whole  day's  subsistence.  If  he  has  absolutely  no 
other  resources  than  his  labor,  hunger  brings  him  to  his 
knees  the  very  next  morning.  Even  if  he  has  a  little  hoard, 
or  a  couple  of  rooms  full  of  furniture,  he  and  his  family 
can  only  exist  by  the  immediate  sacrifice  of  their  cherished 
provision  against  calamity,  or  the  stripping  of  their  home. 
Sooner  or  later  he  must  come  to  terms,  on  pain  of  starvation 
or  the  workhouse.2  And  since  success  in  the  higgling  of  the 

1  The  latest  critic  of  the  theory  of  Trade  Unionism  denies  this  inequality,  on 
the  ground  that  whilst  the  wage-earners  must  starve  if  the  employers  stand  out, 
the  employers  may  be  driven  into  bankruptcy  if  the  workmen  revolt  (A  Criti- 
cism of  the  Theory  of  Trade?   Unions ',  by  T.   S.  Cree,  Glasgow,  1891,  p.  20). 
But  this  very  argument  assumes  "  a  stoppage  of  work  through  a  strike  " — that  is 
to  say,  deliberately  concerted  action  among  the  wage-earners — the  very  Trade 
Unionism  which  the  writer  declares  to  be  unnecessary. 

2  It  is  interesting  to  find  this  situation  clearly  seen  by  an  unknown  French 
writer  of  1773:   "  Partout  oil  il  y  a  de  tres-grandes  proprietes,   et  par  conse- 
quent, beaucoup  de  journaliers,  voici  comment  s'etablit  naturellement  le  prix  des 
journees  :    le    journalier  demande  une  somme,    le  proprietaire   en   propose  un 
moindre  ;  et  comme  il  ajoute  je  puts  me  passer  de  vous  plusieurs  jours,  voyez  si 
vous  pouvez  vous  passer  de  moi  vingt-quatre  heures,  on  sait  que  le  marche  est 
bientot  conclu  au  prejudice  du  journalier." — Eloge  de  Jean  Baptiste  Colbert,  par 
Monsieur  P.   (Paris,    1773),   p.    8.      Three  years  later  Adam  Smith  remarked 
that  "  in  the  long  run   the  workman  may  be  as  necessary  to  his  master  as  his 
master  is  to  him,  but  the  necessity  is  not  so   immediate"  (Wealth  of  Nations, 
London,  1776,   Book  I.  ch.   viii.  p.   30  of  M'Cullochs  edition).      Du  Cellier 
(Histoire  des  Classes  Laborieuses  en  France}  observes  that  "  the  struggle  in  the 
labor  market  too  often  takes  place,  not  between  two  equal  contracting  parties, 
but  between  a  money-bag  and  a  stomach"  (p.  324).      "In  the  general  course 
of  human  nature,"  remarked   the  shrewd  founders  of  the  American   Constitu- 
tion,  "power   over   a  man's  subsistence  amounts   to  a  power  over  his  will" 
(Federalist,  No.  Ixxix.), 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  657 

market  is  largely  determined  by  the  relative  eagerness  of  the 
parties  to  come  to  terms — especially  if  this  eagerness  cannot 
be  hid — it  is  now  agreed,  even  if  on  this  ground  alone,  "  that 
manual  laborers  as  a  class  are  at  a  disadvantage  in  bar- 
gaining." 1 

But  there  is  also  a  marked  difference  between  the  parties 
in  that  knowledge  of  the  circumstances  which  is  requisite 
for  successful  higgling.  "  The  art  of  bargaining,"  observed 
Jevons,  "  mainly  consists  in  the  buyer  ascertaining  the  lowest 
price  at  which  the  seller  is  willing  to  part  with  his  object, 
without  disclosing,  if  possible,  the  highest  price  which  he,  the 
buyer,  is  willing  to  give.  .  .  .  The  power  of  reading  another 
man's  thoughts  is  of  high  importance  in  business."  2  Now  the 
essential  economic  weakness  of  the  isolated  workman's  posi- 
tion, as  we  have  just  described  it,  is  necessarily  known  to  the 
employer  and  his  foreman.  The  isolated  workman,  on  the 
other  hand,  is  ignorant  of  the  employer's  position.  Even  in 
the  rare  cases  in  which  the  absence  of  a  single  workman  is 
seriously  inconvenient  to  the  capitalist  employer,  this  is 
unknown  to  any  one  outside  his  office.  What  is  even  more 
important,  the  employer,  knowing  the  state  of  the  market 
for  his  product,  can  form  a  clear  opinion  of  how  much  it  is 
worth  his  while  to  give,  rather  than  go  without  the  labor 
altogether,  or  rather  than  postpone  it  for  a  few  weeks. 
But  the  isolated  workman,  unaided  by  any  Trade  Union 
official,  and  unable  to  communicate  even  with  the  workmen 
in  other  towns,  is  wholly  in  the  dark  as  to  how  much  he 
might  ask. 

With  these  two  important  disadvantages,  it  is  compara- 
tively a  minor  matter  that  the  manual  worker  is,  from  his 

1  Principles  of  Economics,  by  Professor  A.   Marshall,  3rd   edition  (London, 
1895),  Book  VI.  ch.  iv.  p.  649.      Professor  Marshall  adds  that  "  the  effects  of  the 
laborer's  disadvantage  in  bargaining  are  therefore  cumulative  in  two  ways.      It 
lowers  his  wages  ;  and,  as  we  have  seen,  this  lowers  his  efficiency  as  a  worker,  and 
thereby  lowers  the  normal  value  of  his  labor.     And  in  addition  it  diminishes  his 
efficiency  as  a  bargainer,  and  thus  increases  the  chance  that  he  will  sell  his  labor 
for  less  than  its  normal  value." 

2  W.  S.  Jevons,  Theory  of  Political  Economy,  3rd  edition  (London,    1888), 
ch.  iv.  p.  124. 

VOL.  II  2  U 


658  Trade  Union  Theory 

position  and  training,  far  less  skilled  than  the  employer  or 
his  foreman  in  the  art  of  bargaining  itself.  This  art  forms 
a  large  part  of  the  daily  life  of  the  entrepreneur,  whilst  the 
foreman  is  specially  selected  for  his  skill  in  engaging  and 
superintending  workmen.  The  manual  worker,  on  the  con- 
trary, has  the  very  smallest  experience  of,  and  practically 
no  training  in,  what  is  essentially  one  of  the  arts  of  the 
capitalist  employer.  He  never  engages  in  any  but  one  sort 
of  bargaining,  and  that  only  on  occasions  which  may  be  infre- 
quent, and  which  in  any  case  make  up  only  a  tiny  fraction 
of  his  life. 

Thus,  in  the  making  of  the  labor  contract  the  isolated 
individual  workman,  unprotected  by  any  combination  with 
his  fellows,  stands  in  all  respects  at  a  disadvantage  compared 
with  the  capitalist  employer.  There  is  an  even  more  serious 
disadvantage  to  come.  The  hiring  of  a  workman,  unlike  a 
contract  for  the  purchase  of  a  commodity,  necessarily  leaves 
many  conditions  not  precisely  determined,  still  less  expressed 
in  any  definite  form.  This  indeterminateness  of  the  labor 
contract  is  in  some  respects  a  drawback  to  the  employer. 
In  return  for  the  specified  wage,  the  workman  has  impliedly 
agreed  to  give  work  of  the  currently  accepted  standard  of 
quantity  and  quality.  The  lack  of  definiteness  in  this  respect 
leaves  him  free  to  skulk  or  to  scamp.  But  against  this  the 
employer  protects  himself  by  providing  supervision  and  by 
requiring  obedience  to  his  foreman,  if  not  also  by  elaborate 
systems  of  fines  and  deductions.  Whenever  there  is  any 
dispute  as  to  the  speed  of  work,  or  the  quality  of  the  output, 
the  foreman's  decision  is  absolute.  To  the  workman,  how- 
ever, the  indeterminateness  of  his  contract  is  a  far  more 
fruitful  source  of  personal  hardship,  against  which  he  has  no 
practicable  remedy.  When  an  additional  "  hand  "  is  taken  on 
in  a  manufacturing  establishment,  practically  the  only  point 
explicitly  agreed  upon  between  him  and  the  foreman  is  the 
amount  of  the  weekly  wage,  or  possibly  the  scale  of  piece- 
work rates.  How  many  hours  he  shall  work,  how  quickly 
or  how  intensely  he  is  to  exert  himself,  what  intervals  will 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  659 

be  allowed  for  meals,  what  fines  and  deductions  he  will  be 
subject  to,  what  provision  is  made  for  warmth  and  shelter, 
the  arrangements  for  ventilation  and  prevention  of  accidents, 
the  sanitary  accommodation,  the  noise,  the  smell  and  the  dirt, 
the  foreman's  temper  and  the  comrades'  manners — all  this 
has  to  be  taken  for  granted,  it  being  always  implied  in  the 
engagement  that  the  workman  accepts  the  conditions  existing 
in  the  employer's  establishment,  and  obeys  all  his  lawful 
commands.  It  may  be  urged  that,  if  the  conditions  are 
worse  than  is  customary,  the  workman  will  not  accept  the 
situation,  unless  he  is  offered  higher  wages.  But  until  he  has 
made  his  contract  and  actually  begun  work,  he  cannot  know 
what  the  conditions  are,  even  if  he  could  estimate  their  dis- 
advantage in  terms  of  money,  and  stand  out  for  the  higher 
price.  Moreover,  unless  fixed  by  law  or  Collective  Bargain- 
ing, these  conditions  may  at  any  moment  be  changed  at 
the  will  of  the  employer,  or  the  caprice  of  the  fore- 
man. Thus,  when  the  isolated  workman  has  made  his 
bargain,  he  has  no  assurance  that  it  will  be  adhered  to, 
as  regards  any  element  other  than  the  money  wage,  and 
even  this  may  be  eaten  into  by  unforeseen  fines  and  de- 
ductions. On  all  the  other  conditions  of  employment  he 
is,  under  an  unregulated  industrial  system,  absolutely  in  the 
hands  of  the  employer  for  the  period  of  his  engagement. 
The  workman  may,  indeed,  give  up  his  situation,  and  throw 
himself  again  on  the  market,  to  incur  once  more  the  risk  of 
losing  his  subsistence  whilst  seeking  a  new  place,  and  to 
suffer  afresh  the  perils  of  Individual  Bargaining ;  but  even 
if  he  makes  up  his  mind  rather  to  lose  his  employment 
than  to  put  up  with  intolerable  conditions,  he  is  not  legally 
free  to  do  so  without  proper  notice,1  and  for  his  sufferings 
during  this  period  he  has  no  redress. 

Such  are   the   disadvantages  at  which,  when   the   labor 

1  Leaving  work  without  giving  the  notice  expressed  or  implied  in  the  contract 
renders  the  workman  liable  to  be  sued  for  damages  ;  and  such  actions  by  the 
employer  against  recalcitrant  workmen  are  frequent,  especially  in  the  coal-mining 
industry. 


66o  Trade  Union  Theory 

market  is  in  a  state  of  perfect  equilibrium,  the  isolated 
individual  workman  stands  in  bargaining  with  the  capitalist 
employer.  But  it  is,  to  say  the  least  of  it,  unusual,  in  any 
trade  in  this  country,  for  there  to  be  no  more  workmen 
applying  for  situations  than  there  are  situations  to  be  filled. 
When  the  unemployed  are  crowding  round  the  factory  gates 
every  morning,  it  is  plain  to  each  man  that,  unless  he  can 
induce  the  foreman  to  select  him  rather  than  another,  his 
chance  of  subsistence  for  weeks  to  come  may  be  irretrievably 
lost.  Under  these  circumstances  bargaining,  in  the  case  of 
isolated  individual  workmen,  becomes  absolutely  impossible. 
The  foreman  has  only  to  pick  his  man,  and  tell  him  the 
terms.  Once  inside  the  gates,  the  lucky  workman  knows 
that  if  he  grumbles  at  any  of  the  surroundings,  however 
intolerable  ;  if  he  demurs  to  any  speeding-up,  lengthening  of 
the  hours,  or  deductions  ;  or  if  he  hesitates  to  obey  any 
order,  however  unreasonable,  he  condemns  himself  once  more 
to  the  semi-starvation  and  misery  of  unemployment.  For 
the  alternative  to  the  foreman  is  merely  to  pick  another  man 
from  the  eager  crowd,  whilst  the  difference  to  the  employer 
becomes  incalculably  infinitesimal.  And  it  is  a  mistake  to 
suppose  that  the  workman's  essential  disadvantages  in 
bargaining  disappear  in  times  of  good  trade,  or  even  when 
employers  are  complaining  of  a  scarcity  of  hands.  The 
workman,  it  is  true,  need  not  then  fear  starvation,  for  he 
may  rely  on  finding  another  employer.  But  if  he  refuses 
the  first  employer's  terms,  he  still  irrevocably  loses  his  day's 
subsistence,  and  runs  a  risk  of  seeing  subsequent  days  pass 
in  the  same  manner.  Moreover,  the  tramp  after  another 
employer  may  often  mean  the  breaking  up  of  his  home, 
removal  from  his  friends,  dislocation  of  his  children's  educa- 
tion, and  all  the  hundred  and  one  discomforts  of  migration 
or  exile.1  The  employer,  on  the  other  hand,  will  be  induced 

1  Thus,  in  1896,  a  year  of  exceptionally  good  trade,  between  five  and  six 
hundred  members  of  the  Associated  Shipwrights'  Society  obtained  advances  of 
railway  fares  to  enable  them  to  move  from  their  homes,  where  they  were  un- 
employed, to  other  towns  where  work  was  to  be  had  ;  see  Fifteenth  Annual 
Report  of  the  Associated  Shipwrights'  Society  (Newcastle,  1897),  pp.  164-179. 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  66 1 

to  offer  higher  terms,  rather  than  run  the  risk  of  foregoing 
some  part  of  the  increased  profits  of  brisk  times.  But  the 
extent  of  the  "  debatable  land "  is,  in  these  times  of  high 
profits,  enormously  increased,  and  no  one  but  the  employer 
himself  knows  by  how  much.  Here  the  difference  in  the 
knowledge  of  the  circumstances  becomes  all-important,  and 
fatally  disadvantageous  to  the  isolated  workman.  The 
employer  knows  about  what  other  firms  have  been  paying 
for  their  labor,  and  to  what  extent  there  is  a  real  scarcity  of 
workmen  ;  hence  he  can  judge  how  little  he  need  offer  to 
make  his  place  seem  worth  accepting  to  the  unemployed 
workman.  The  isolated  workman,  on  the  other  hand,  has 
no  knowledge  whether  the  scarcity  of  labor  extends  beyond 
his  own  town,  or  is  likely  to  be  prolonged  ;  whilst  he  has 
not  the  slightest  idea  of  how  much  he  might  stand  out  for, 
and  yet  be  taken  on.  In  short,  it  would  be  easy  to  argue 
that,  in  spite  of  the  actual  rise  of  his  wages  in  times  of  good 
trade,  it  is  just  when  profits  are  largest  that  the  isolated 
workman  stands  at  the  greatest  economic  disadvantage  in 
the  division  of  the  "  debatable  land." 

So  far  the  argument  that  the  isolated  workman,  unpro- 
tected by  anything  in  the  nature  of  Trade  Unionism,  must 
necessarily  get  the  worst  of  the  bargain,  rests  on  the  assump- 
tion that  the  capitalist  employer  will  take  full  advantage  of 
his  strategic  strength,  and  beat  each  class  of  wage-earners 
down  to  the  lowest  possible  terms.  In  so  far  as  this  result 
depends  upon  the  will  and  intention  of  each  individual 
employer,  the  assumption  is  untrue.  A  capitalist  employer 
who  looks  forward,  not  to  one  but  to  many  years'  produc- 
tion, and  who  regards  his  business  as  a  valuable  property  to 
be  handed  down  from  one  generation  to  another,  will,  if  only 
for  his  own  sake,  bear  in  mind  the  probable  effect  of  any 
reduction  upon  the  permanent  efficiency  of  the  establish- 
ment. He  will  know  that  he  cannot  subject  his  work- 
people to  bad  conditions  of  employment  without  causing 
them  imperceptibly  to  deteriorate  in  the  quantity  or  quality 
of  the  service  that  they  render.  As  an  organiser  of  men,  he 


662  Trade  Union  Theory 

will  readily  appreciate  to  how  great  an  extent  the  smooth 
and  expeditious  working  of  a  complicated  industrial  concern 
depends  on  each  man  feeling  that  he  is  being  treated  with 
consideration,  and  that  he  is  receiving  at  least  as  much 
as  he  might  be  earning  elsewhere.  But  apart  from  these 
considerations  of  mere  self-interest,  the  typical  capitalist 
manufacturer  of  the  present  generation,  with  his  increasing 
education  and  refinement,  his  growing  political  interests  and 
public  spirit,  will,  so  long  as  his  own  customary  income  is 
not  interfered  with,  take  a  positive  pleasure  in  augmenting 
the  wages  and  promoting  the  comfort  of  his  workpeople. 
Unfortunately,  the  intelligent,  far-sighted,  and  public-spirited 
employer  is  not  master  of  the  situation.  Unless  he  is  pro- 
tected by  one  or  other  of  the  dykes  or  bulwarks  presently  to 
be  described,  he  is  constantly  finding  himself  as  powerless 
as  the  workman  to  withstand  the  pressure  of  competitive 
industry.  How  this  competitive  pressure  pushes  him,  in 
sheer  self-defence,  to  take  as  much  advantage  of  his  work- 
people as  the  most  grasping  and  short-sighted  of  his  rivals, 
we  shall  understand  by  examining  the  next  link  in  the 
chain. 

Paradoxical  as  it  may  appear,  in  the  highly-developed 
commercial  system  of  the  England  of  to-day  the  capitalist 
manufacturer  stands  at  as  great  a  relative  disadvantage  to 
the  wholesale  trader  as  the  isolated  workman  does  to  the 
capitalist  manufacturer.  In  the  higgling  of  the  market  with 
the  wholesale  trader  who  takes  his  product,  the  capitalist 
manufacturer  exhibits  the  same  inferiority  of  strategic  posi- 
tion with  regard  to  the  alternative,  with  regard  to  know- 
ledge of  the  circumstances,  and  with  regard  to  bargaining 
capacity.  First,  we  have  the  fact  that  the  manufacturer 
stands  to  lose  more  by  failing  to  sell  his  product  with 
absolute  regularity,  than  the  wholesale  trader  does  by 
temporarily  abstaining  from  buying.  To  the  manufacturer, 
with  his  capital  locked  up  in  mills  and  plant,  continuity  of 
employment  is  all-important.  If  his  mills  have  to  stop  even 
for  a  single  day,  he  has  irrevocably  lost  that  day's  gross 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  663 

income,  including  out-of-pocket  expenses  for  necessary 
salaries  and  maintenance.  To  the  wholesale  trader,  on  the 
other  hand,  it  is  comparatively  a  small  matter  that  his  stocks 
run  low  for  a  short  time.  His  unemployed  working-capital 
is,  at  worst,  gaining  deposit  interest  at  the  bank,  and  all  he 
foregoes  is  a  fraction  of  his  profits  for  the  year.  Moreover, 
as  the  wholesale  trader  makes  his  income  by  a  tiny  profit 
per  cent  on  a  huge  turnover,  any  particular  transaction  is 
comparatively  unimportant  to  him.  The  manufacturer, 
earning  a  relatively  large  percentage  on  a  small  turnover,  is 
much  more  concerned  about  each  part  of  it.  In  short, 
whilst  the  capitalist  manufacturer  is  "  a  combination  in 
himself"  compared  with  the  thousand  workmen  whom  he 
employs,  the  wholesale  trader  is  "a  combination  in  himself" 
compared  with  the  hundreds  of  manufacturers  from  whom 
he  buys.  The  disparity  is  no  less  great  with  regard  to  that 
knowledge  of  the  market  which  is  invaluable  in  bargaining. 
The  manufacturer,  even  if  he  has  a  resident  agent  at  the 
chief  commercial  centre,  can  never  aspire  to  anything  like 
the  wide  outlook  over  all  the  world,  and  the  network  of 
communications  from  retail  traders  and  shipping  agents  in 
every  town,  which  make  up  the  business  organisation  of  the 
wholesale  trader.  The  trader,  in  short,  alone  possesses  an 
up-to-date  knowledge  of  the  market  in  all  its  aspects  ;  he 
alone  receives  the  latest  information  as  to  what  shopkeepers 
find  most  in  demand,  and  what  native  and  foreign  manu- 
facturers are  offering  for  sale.  With  all  this  superiority  of 
knowledge,  it  is  a  minor  matter  that,  as  compared  with  the 
manufacturer,  immersed  in  the  organisation  of  labor  and  the 
improvement  of  technical  processes,  the  wholesale  trader  is  a 
specialist  in  bargaining,  trained  by  his  whole  life  in  the  art 
of  buying  in  the  cheapest  and  selling  in  the  dearest  market.1 

1  Where,  as  is  the  case  in  many  trades,  the  wholesale  trader  sends  out 
travellers  to  visit  the  retail  shopkeepers,  the  manufacturer  is  even  more 
dependent  on  him.  For  these  travellers  have  great  power  to  "push "one 
line  of  goods  rather  than  another,  and  if  any  wholesale  house  has  a  well- 
established  connection — still  more,  if  its  shopkeeping  clients  are  in  any  way 
dependent  on  it — it  can  seriously  injure  a  particular  manufacturer  by  boycotting 


664  Trade  Union  Theory 

Thus,  when  the  manufacturer  negotiates  for  an  order,  he 
is,  within  certain  undefined  limits,  at  the  mercy  of  the  whole- 
sale trader.  He  is  told  that  the  price  of  his  product  is  too 
high  to  attract  customers ;  that  the  shopkeepers  find  no 
demand  for  it  ;  that  foreign  producers  are  daily  encroaching 
on  the  neutral  markets  ;  and,  finally,  that  there  has  just 
come  an  offer  from  a  rival  manufacturer  to  supply  the  same 
kind  of  article  at  a  lower  price.  The  manufacturer  may 
doubt  these  statements,  but  he  has  no  means  of  disproving 
them.  He  is  keenly  alive  to  the  fact  that  his  brother  manu- 
facturers are  as  eager  as  he  is  to  get  the  order,  and  some  of 
them,  he  knows,  are  always  striving  to  undercut  prices. 
Unless  he  is  a  man  of  substance,  able  to  wait  for  more 
profitable  orders,  or  unless  his  product  is  a  speciality  of  his 
own,  which  no  one  else  makes,  he  is  almost  certain  to  be 
tempted,  rather  than  lose  the  business,  to  accept  a  lower 
offer  than  he  meant  to.  The  price  he  has  accepted  can 
only  work  out  in  a  profit  by  some  lowering  of  the  cost  of 
production.  He  consults  his  partners  and  his  foreman  as  to 
how  this  can  be  effected.  Some  slight  improvement  may 
be  possible  in  the  technical  process,  or  a  new  machine  may 
be  introduced.  But  this  takes  both  time  and  capital.  If 
neither  law  nor  combination  stands  in  the  way,  it  is  far 
easier  to  meet  the  emergency  by  extracting  more  work  from 
his  operatives  for  the  same  pay — by  "speeding-up,"  by 
lengthening  hours,  by  increased  rigor  in  respect  of  fines 
and  deductions,  or  by  a  positive  reduction  of  time  wages  or 
piecework  rates.  Any  idea  of  introducing  better  sanitary 
accommodation  or  further  fencing  of  machinery  is  given  up, 
and  all  the  working  expenses  are  reduced  to  their  lowest 
limit.  Whatever  reluctance  the  good  manufacturer  may 
have  to  take  this  course  necessarily  disappears  when  he  finds 

his  product.  The  manufacturer  may,  of  course,  put  his  own  travellers  on  the 
road.  But  it  is  clearly  more  economical  for  the  wholesale  house  to  maintain  the 
travellers,  so  that  the  little  shopkeeper  can  get  all  his  stock  at  once,  than  for  the 
manufacturer  of  each  article  to  have  his  own  separate  staff.  The  continued  exist- 
ence of  the  wholesale  trader  is  thus  as  economically  advantageous  to  all  but  the 
largest  manufacturers  as  it  is  to  all  but  the  largest  retailers, 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  665 

his  more  necessitous  or  less  scrupulous  rivals  actually  fore- 
stalling him.  For  just  as  in  every  trade  there  are  far-sighted 
and  kindly-disposed  employers  who  feel  for  their  workpeople 
as  for  themselves,  so  there  are  others  in  whom  the  desire  for 
personal  gain  is  the  dominating  passion,  and  whose  lack  of 
intelligence,  or  financial  "  shadiness,"  shuts  them  out  from 
any  other  policy  than  "grinding  the  faces  of  the  poor." 
The  manufacturer  of  this  type  needs  no  pressure  from  the 
wholesale  trader  to  stimulate  him  to  take  the  fullest  possible 
advantage  of  the  necessities  of  his  workpeople  ;  and  in  face 
of  competition  of  this  kind  the  good  employer  has  no  choice 
but  to  yield.  Anything,  he  says  to  himself,  is  better  for  his 
workpeople  than  stopping  his  own  mill  and  driving  the 
trade  into  such  channels. 

There  is,  moreover,  another  reason  that  makes  the 
manufacturer  yield  to  the  constant  nibbling  at  price,  which 
forms  so  large  a  part  of  the  art  of  the  wholesale  trader.  In 
order  that  the  manufacturer  may  make  a  profit  on  the  year's 
trading  he  must  obtain  for  his  output,  not  only  enough  to 
cover  the  outgoings  for  wages  and  raw  material — the  "  prime 
cost "  of  the  finished  product — but  also  the  standing  charges 
of  the  manufactory,  termed  by  Professor  Marshall  the  "supple- 
mentary cost."  When  a  manufacturer  is  pressed  to  make  a 
bargain  at  the  lowest  price,  rather  than  see  his  mill  stand  idle, 
it  is  the  "  prime  cost "  which  he  thinks  of  as  the  minimum  that 
he  can  accept  without  loss,  since  the  standing  charges  will 
go  on  anyhow.  Each  manufacturer  in  turn  prefers  to  sell  at 
"  prime  cost "  rather  than  not  get  an  order  at  all,  with  the 
result,  as  the  saying  is,  of  "  spoiling  the  market "  for  them- 
selves and  their  rivals  alike.1  The  standing  charges  have  to 
be  met  somehow,  and  the  harassed  employer  is  forced  to  turn 

1  It  was  especially  this  effect  of  manufacturers'  competition  to  secure  orders — 
the  frequent  sales  at  prices  covering  "  prime  cost "  only — that  led  to  the  formation 
of  the  remarkable  "alliances  "  in  the  Birmingham  hardware  trades  described  in  the 
chapter  on  "  The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism."  To  secure  protection  against 
the  resulting  constant  degradation  of  price  is  the  usual  motive  for  manufacturers' 
rings  and  syndicates.  The  difference  between  "  prime  cost  "  and  "supplementary 
cost "  in  English  industry  is  worth  further  economic  and  statistical  investigation  ; 
see  especially  the  chapter  entitled  "  Cost  Taking,"  in  The  New  Trades  Combina- 


666  Trade  Union  Theory 

for  relief  to  any  possible  cutting-down  of  the  expenses  of 
production,  wages  not  excluded.  Meanwhile,  the  wholesale 
trader  sees  no  possible  objection  to  the  reduction  he  has 
effected.  To  him  it  is  of  no  pecuniary  consequence  that  a 
large  proportion  of  the  manufacturers  of  a  particular  article 
are  only  just  managing  to  cover  its  "  prime  cost,"  and  are 
thus  really  losing  money,  or  that  the  workpeople  in  the 
hardest  pressed  mills  or  the  least  fortunate  districts  are, 
owing  to  a  worsening  of  conditions,  beginning  to  degrade  in 
character  and  efficiency.  If  the  product  seriously  falls  off  in 
quality  relatively  to  the  price  demanded,  he  can  go  else- 
where ;  and  he  makes,  moreover,  quite  as  large  a  percentage 
on  low-grade  goods  as  on  those  of  standard  excellence. 
And  if  he  thinks  about  it  at  all,  he  regards  himself  as  the 
representative,  not  of  a  particular  class  of  producers,  but  of 
the  whole  world  of  consumers,  to  whom  it  is  an  obvious 
advantage  that  the  price  should  be  lowered. 

We  need  not  wonder,  therefore,  at  the  chronic  complaints 
of  manufacturers  in  every  trade,  that  profits  are  always  being 
reduced,  so  that  business  is  scarcely  worth  carrying  on. 
Even  in  years  of  national  prosperity,  when  Income  Tax  and 
Death  Duties  show  that  vast  fortunes  are  being  made  some- 
where, the  employers  who  have  no  individual  speciality, 
whose  output  is  taken  by  the  wholesale  trader,  and 
who  are  unable  to  form  a  "  ring "  or  "  alliance "  to  keep 
up  prices,  bitterly  complain  that  it  is  as  much  as  they 
can  do  to  cover  the  "  prime  cost "  of  their  products,  or 
that,  at  best,  they  find  themselves  earning  only  the  barest 
interest  on  capital.1  For  the  influences  which  we  have 

tion  Movement,  by  E.  J.  Smith  (Birmingham,  1895).  For  statistics  relating  to 
American  industry  the  student  may  consult  the  Report  of  the  Commissioner  of 
Labor  in  the  United  States  for  i8go  (Washington,  1891)  and  the  valuable  series 
of  Reports  of  Statistics  of  Manufactures  of  Massachusetts  from  1886  to  i8g6. 
Particulars  of  English  factory  usage  will  be  found  in  Factory  Accounts,  by 
E.  Garcke  and  J.  M.  Fells.  The  only  English  statistics  consist  of  a  brief 
Report  on  the  Relation  of  Wages  to  the  Cost  of  Production,  C.  6535,  1891. 

In  his  Principles  of  Economics,  Book  V.  chaps,  iv.  and  vii.,  Prof.  Marshall  has 
described  the  relative  influence  on  exchange  value  of  "prime"  and  "supple- 
mentary "  cost. 

1  How  keenly  this  pressure  is  felt  by  the  manufacturers  who  are  exposed  tq 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  667 

described  affect  the  higgling  of  the  market  when  the  real 
demand  of  the  consumers  is  brisk  as  well  as  when  it  is 
restricted.  They  amount,  in  fact,  under  a  system  of  free 
and  unregulated  competition,  to  a  permanent  pressure  on 
manufacturing  employers  to  take  the  fullest  possible  ad- 
vantage of  their  strategic  superiority  in  bargaining  with  the 
isolated  workman. 

But  we  should  make  a  mistake  if  we  imagined  that  the 
pressure  originated  with  the  wholesale  trader.  Just  as  the 
manufacturer  is  conscious  of  his  weakness  in  face  of  the 

full  competition,  may  be  judged  from  the  following  speech  from  Lord  Masham — 
the  Samuel  Lister  who  has  made  a  colossal  fortune  from  his  legally  protected 
patents.  Having  explained  why  the  Manningham  Mills  had  earned  less  than 
they  were  expected  to  earn,  Lord  Masham  went  on  to  argue  that  they  had  earned 
a  great  deal  more  than  most  other  concerns.  "  Lister  &  Co.  had  earned  during 
the  eight  years  it  had  been  a  company  an  average  of  4  per  cent  on  the  entire  capital 
— that  was,  throwing  debentures,  preference  shares,  and  ordinary  stock  all  into 
one  pool.  If  the  money  had  been  invested  in  agriculture,  what  would  have 
happened?  He  had  invested  the  same  amount  in  agriculture,  for  which  he 
got  2^  per  cent  and  he  bought  to  receive  3.  He  had  lost  as  much  money  nearly  in 
agriculture  as  he  had  by  his  investment  in  Lister  &  Co.  Then  he  would  go  on 
to  cotton.  He  saw  in  the  Saturday  Review  an  article  stating  that  the  cotton 
spinning  trade  was  paying,  on  the  average  of  a  large  number  of  limited  companies, 
I ^  or  i^r  per  cent.  That  looked  so  outrageous  that  he  could  not  believe  it.  He  cut 
the  statement  out,  and  sent  it  to  a  gentleman  who  was  in  the  cotton  trade,  and 
whose  father  was  in  the  cotton  trade  before  him.  That  gentleman  sent  it  back 
again,  saying  that  it  was  absolutely  true,  and  he  said,  '  I  will  tell  you  something 
else — I  challenge  the  whole  trade  of  Lancashire,  and  I  will  guarantee  that  the 
whole  trade  of  Lancashire  is  not  on  the  capital  invested  paying  as  much  as 
Consols — not  the  spinning  alone,  but  the  whole  manufacturing  trade  of  Lancashire.' 
So  much  with  regard  to  two  industries.  Coming  to  iron,  what  was  the  state  of 
the  iron  trade  two  or  three  years  ago  ?  Three  years  ago,  at  any  rate,  half  the 
iron  concerns  in  England  were  standing,  and  those  that  were  at  work  were 
making  no  profit.  They  were  declaring  no  dividend,  and  therefore,  if  the  two 
good  years  which  they  had  had  just  recently  were  added  to  the  back  years,  he 
would  guarantee  that  during  the  time  of  Lister  &  Co.  the  iron  concerns  had  not 
made  on  their  capital  the  4  per  cent  that  Manningham  had.  Then  he  came  to 
another  industry,  on  which  he  could  speak  with  authority.  It  was  one  of  the 
greatest  industries  in  England,  and  employed  over  800,000  persons.  If  it  went  on 
increasing  as  it  had  done  it  would  be  our  greatest  industry.  He  referred  to  coal. 
He  had  been  in  the  coal  hole  (laughter),  and  he  knew  that  for  several  years  he 
made  no  interest,  and  he  had  very  nearly  as  much  money  invested  in  it  as  in 
Manningham." 

This  speech  was  made  in  January  1897,  at  a  tmie  °f  roaring  good  trade,  after 
several  years  of  more  than  average  prosperity,  when  the  aggregate  profits  of  Great 
Britain  as  a  whole  were  apparently  larger  than  they  had  been  at  any  previous 
period  of  its  history  ! 


668  Trade  Union  Theory 

wholesale  trader,  so  the  wholesale  trader  feels  himself  help- 
less before  the  retail  shopkeeper  to  whom  he  sells  his  stock. 
Here  the  inferiority  is  not  in  any  greater  loss  that  would 
arise  if  no  business  were  done,  for  the  retailer  is  impelled  to 
buy  by  motives  exactly  as  strong  as  those  which  impel  the 
wholesale  house  to  sell.  Nor  is  it  in  any  difference  in  bargain- 
ing power.  In  both  these  respects  the  wholesale  house  may 
even  have  the  advantage  over  the  shopkeepers.  But  the 
shopkeepers  have  a  closer  and  more  up-to-date  knowledge 
of  exactly  what  it  is  that  customers  are  asking  for,  and, 
what  is  far  more  important,  they  can  to  some  extent  direct 
this  demand  by  placing,  before  the  great  ignorant  body  of 
consumers,  one  article  rather  than  another.  They  have, 
therefore,  to  be  courted  by  the  wholesale  trader,  and  induced 
to  push  the  particular  "  lines "  that  he  is  interested  in. 
There  is,  however,  yet  another,  and  even  a  more  active,  cause 
for  the  weakness  in  strategic  position  of  the  wholesale  trader. 
His  main  economic  function  is  to  "  nurse  "  the  small  shop- 
keeper. The  little  retailer,  with  a  narrow  range  of  clients, 
cannot  buy  sufficient  of  any  one  article  to  enable  him  to  deal 
directly  with  the  maker  ;  he  cannot,  moreover,  communicate 
with  the  large  number  of  separate  manufacturers  whose 
products  he  sells  ;  nor  could  he  spare  the  capital  to  pay  cash 
for  his  stock.  The  wholesale  trader  accordingly  acts  as  his 
intermediary.  In  the  large  city  warehouse,  the  shopkeeper 
finds  collected  before  him  the  products  of  all  the  manufacturers 
in  the  various  branches  of  his  trade  ;  he  can  take  as  small  a 
quantity  of  each  as  he  chooses,  and  he  is  given  as  much 
credit  as  his  turnover  requires.  As  long  as  this  state  of 
things  lasts  the  wholesale  trader  holds  the  field.  But  there 
has  been,  for  the  last  half  century,  a  constant  tendency 
towards  a  revolution  in  retail  trade.  In  one  town  or  one 
district  after  another  there  grow  up,  instead  of  numberless 
little  shops,  large  retail  businesses,  possessing  as  much 
capital  and  commercial  knowledge  as  the  wholesale  house 
itself,  and  able  to  give  orders  that  even  the  wealthiest 
manufacturers  are  glad  to  receive.  Hence  the  wholesale 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  669 

house  stands  in  constant  danger  of  losing  his  clients,  the 
smaller  ones  because  they  cannot  buy  cheaply  enough  to 
resist  the  cutting  prices  of  their  mammoth  rivals,  and  these 
leviathans  themselves  because  they  are  able  to  do  without 
their  original  intermediaries.  The  wholesale  trader's  only 
chance  of  retaining  their  custom  is  to  show  a  greater 
capacity  for  screwing  down  the  prices  of  the  manufacturers 
than  even  the  largest  shopkeeper  possesses.  He  is  therefore 
driven,  as  a  matter  of  life  and  death,  to  concentrate  his 
attention  on  extracting,  from  one  manufacturer  after  another, 
a  continual  succession  of  heavy  discounts  or  special  terms  of 
some  kind.  This,  then,  is  the  fundamental  reason  why  the 
manufacturer  finds  the  wholesale  trader  so  relentless  in 
taking  advantage  of  his  strategic  position.  Though  often 
performing  a  service  of  real  economic  advantage  to  the 
community,  he  can  only  continue  to  exist  by  a  constant 
"  squeezing  "  of  all  the  other  agents  in  production.1 

We  come  now  to  the  last  link  in  the  chain,  the  competi- 
tion between  retail  shopkeepers  to  secure  customers.  Here 
the  superiority  in  knowledge  and  technical  skill  is  on  the 
side  of  the  seller,  but  this  is  far  outweighed  by  the  excep- 
tional freedom  of  the  buyer.  The  shopkeeper,  it  is  true,  is 

1  The  effect  of  competitive  pressure  in  reducing  the  percentage  of  profits  to 
turnover  is  well  seen  in  the  extreme  cases  in  which  one  or  more  of  the  stages  are 
omitted.  In  the  wholesale  clothing  trade,  for  instance,  there  may  be,  as  we  have 
seen,  only  a  single  grade  of  capitalists  between  the  "sweated"  woman  trouser- 
hand  and  the  purchasing  consumer.  This  wholesale  clothier,  though  he  makes  a 
huge  income  for  himself,  extracts  only  the  most  infinitesimal  sum  out  of  each 
pair  of  trousers  or  "juvenile  suit."  His  success  depends  upon  the  fact  that  he 
has  a  colossal  trade,  dealing  every  year  in  millions  of  garments,  and  turning  over 
his  moderate  capital  with  exceptional  rapidity.  Even  if  he  were  sentimentally 
affected  by  the  fact  that  the  women  to  whom  his  firm  gives  out  its  millions  of 
garments  earned  only  six  to  ten  shillings  a  week,  he  could  not  appreciably  raise 
their  wages  by  foregoing  his  whole  profit,  seeing  that  this  amounts,  perhaps,  only 
to  a  penny  a  garment.  Or,  to  take  another  instance,  the  original  shareholders 
in  the  Civil  Service  Supply  Association,  who  receive  profits  at  the  rate  of  literally 
hundreds  per  cent  per  annum,  cannot  afford  to  put  any  check  on  their  directors' 
zeal  for  screwing  down  the  manufacturers,  or  on  their  foremen's  assiduity  in  keep- 
ing down  wages  in  their  own  producing  departments  ;  for  though  the  profit  is 
colossal,  compared  with  the  capital  invested,  it  is  derived  from  tiny  percentages 
on  millions  of  transactions,  and,  if  shared  by  all  the  wage-earners  concerned  in 
the  production  and  distribution  of  the  articles,  would  amount  to  an  infinitesimal 
addition  to  their  weekly  wages. 


670  Trade  Union  Theory 

not  bound  to  sell  any  particular  article  at  any  particular 
time.  But  he  must,  on  pain  of  bankruptcy,  attract  a  constant 
stream  of  customers  for  his  wares.  The  customer,  on  the 
other  hand,  is  as  free  as  air.  He  can  buy  in  one  shop  as 
well  as  in  another.  He  is  not  even  bound  to  buy  at  all,  and 
may  abstain,  not  only  without  loss,  but  with  a  positive  saving 
to  his  pocket.  He  must,  in  short,  be  tempted  to  buy,  and 
to  this  end  is  bent  all  the  shopkeeper's  knowledge  and 
capacity.  Now,  with  regard  to  the  general  run  of  com- 
modities, the  only  way  of  tempting  the  great  mass  of  con- 
sumers to  buy  is  to  offer  the  article  at  what  they  consider  a 
low  price.  Hence  a  shopkeeper  is  always  on  the  look-out 
for  something  which  he  can  sell  at  a  lower  price  than  has 
hitherto  been  customary,  or  cheaper  than  his  competitors  are 
selling  it  at.  Competition  between  shopkeepers  becomes, 
therefore,  in  all  such  cases  entirely  a  matter  of  cutting  prices, 
and  the  old-fashioned,  steady -going  business,  which  once 
contentedly  paid  whatever  price  the  wholesale  trader  asked, 
is  driven  to  look  as  sharply  after  "cheap  lines"  as  the  keenest 
trader.  It  might  be  suggested  that  a  shopkeeper  could 
equally  outbid  his  rivals  if  he  offered  better  quality  at  the 
same  price.  But  this  would  be  to  misunderstand  the 
psychology  of  the  individual  consumer.1  Owing  to  his  lack 
of  technical  knowledge,  to  say  nothing  of  his  imperfect  means 
of  testing  his  purchase,  the  only  fact  that  he  can  grasp 
is,  with  regard  to  all  nondescript  commodities,  the  retail 
money  price,  and  all  temptation  must  reach  his  mind  through 
this,  the  only  medium.  Under  these  circumstances,  it  is  easy 
to  understand  how  the  revolution  in  retail  trade,  to  which  we 
have  already  referred,  plays  into  the  hands  of  the  customer. 
The  mammoth  establishments,  having  a  much  lower  per- 
centage of  working  expenses  to  turn  over,  are  able  to  sell 

1  Even  the  shops  which  rely  on  a  reputation  for  quality  as  their  main  attrac- 
tion, do  not  commit  the  mistake  o'f  merely  offering  a  better  article  at  the  same 
price  as  is  elsewhere  charged  for  common  goods.  If  they  did,  they  would  quickly 
find  their  customers  deserting  them.  To  retain  the  limited  class  of  well-to-do 
purchasers  who  insist  on  the  best  quality,  a  positively  higher  price  must  be 
charged  1 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  6  7 1 

at  lower  prices  than  the  small  shops,  and  they  naturally  do 
their  utmost  to  attract  customers  by  widely  advertising  their 
cheapness.  The  customers  become  used  to  these  low  prices, 
and  insist  on  them  as  the  only  condition  upon  which  they 
will  continue  to  patronise  the  surviving  smaller  shops.  These, 
unable  to  reduce  their  working  expenses,  complain  piteously 
to  the  wholesale  houses,  who  are,  as  we  have  seen,  driven  to 
supply  them  on  the  lowest  possible  terms,  lest  they  lose  their 
custom  altogether. 

We  thus  arrive  at  the  consumer  as  the  ultimate  source 
of  that  persistent  pressure  on  sellers,  which,  transmitted 
through  the  long  chain  of  bargainings,  finally  crushes  the 
isolated  workman  at  the  base  of  the  pyramid.  Yet,  para- 
doxical as  it  may  seem,  the  consumer  is,  of  all  the  parties  to 
the  transaction,  the  least  personally  responsible  for  the  result. 
For  he  takes  no  active  part  in  the  process.  In  the  great 
market  of  the  world,  he  but  accepts  what  is  spontaneously 
offered  to  him.  He  does  not,  as  a  rule,  even  suggest  to  the 
shopkeeper  that  he  would  like  prices  lowered.  All  he  does 
— and  it  is  enough  to  keep  the  whole  machine  in  motion — 
is  to  demur  to  paying  half  a  crown  for  an  article,  when 
some  one  else  is  offering  him  the  same  thing  for  two  shillings. 
It  may  be  urged  that  he  ought  to  be  ready  to  pay  a  higher 
price  for  a  better  quality.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  consumers, 
whether  rich  or  poor,  do  strive,  in  an  almost  pathetic  way, 
after  some  assurance  of  specific  quality  that  would  reconcile 
them  to  paying  the  higher  price.  They  recognise  that  their 
own  personal  experience  of  any  article  is  too  casual  and 
limited  to  afford  any  trustworthy  guidance,  and  they  accord- 
ingly exhibit  a  touching  faith  in  "  authority  "  of  one  kind  or 
another.  Tradition,  current  hearsay  as  to  what  experts  have 
said,  and  even  the  vague  impression  left  on  the  mind  by  the 
repeated  assertions  of  mendacious  advertisements,  are  all 
reasons  for  remaining  faithful  to  a  particular  commodity,  a 
particular  brand  or  mark,  or  even  a  particular  shop,  irrespec- 
tive of  mere  cheapness.  But  to  enable  the  consumers  to 
exercise  this  choice,  there  must  be  some  easy  means  of 


672  Trade  Union  Theory 

distinguishing  between  rival  wares.  It  so  happens  that  the 
bulk  of  the  consumption  of  the  community  consists  of  goods 
which  cannot  be  labelled  or  otherwise  artificially  distinguished. 
With  regard  to  the  vast  majority  of  the  purchases  of  daily 
life,  no  one  but  an  expert  can,  with  any  assurance,  discrimi- 
nate between  shades  of  quality,  and  the  ordinary  customer  is 
reduced  to  decide  by  price  alone.  Nor  could  he,  even  on 
grounds  of  the  highest  philanthropy,  reasonably  take  any 
other  course.  As  a  practical  man,  he  knows  it  to  be  quite 
impossible  for  him  to  trace  the  article  through  its  various 
stages  of  production  and  distribution,  and  to  discover  whether 
the  extra  sixpence  charged  by  the  dearer  shop  represents 
better  wages  to  any  workman,  or  goes  as  mere  extra  profit 
to  one  or  other  of  the  capitalists  concerned.  If  he  is  an 
economist  he  will  have  a  shrewd  suspicion  that  the  extra 
sixpence  is  most  likely  to  be  absorbed  in  one  form  or  another 
of  that  rent  of  exceptional  opportunity  which  plays  so  large 
a  part  in  industrial  incomes.  Nor  need  he,  in  any  particular 
case,  have  a  presumption  against  low-priced  articles  as  such, 
nor  even  against  a  fall  in  prices.  The  finest  and  most  ex- 
pensive broadcloth,  made  in  the  West  of  England  factories, 
is  the  product  of  worse-paid  labor  than  the  cheap  "  tweeds  " 
of  Dewsbury  or  Batley.  Costly  handmade  lace  is,  in  actual 
fact,  usually  the  outcome  of  cruelly  long  hours  of  labor, 
starvation  wages,  and  incredibly  bad  sanitary  conditions, 
whilst  the  cheap  article,  which  Nottingham  turns  out  by  the 
ton,  is  the  output  of  a  closely  combined  trade,  enjoying  ex- 
ceptionally high  wages,  short  hours,  and  comfortable  homes. 
In  the  same  way  the  great  fall  in  prices,  which  is  so  marked 
a  feature  of  our  time,  is  undoubtedly  due,  in  the  main  (if  not, 
as  some  say,  to  currency  changes),  to  the  natural  and  legiti- 
mate reduction  of  the  real  cost  of  production  ;  to  the  im- 
provement of  technical  processes,  the  cheapening  of  transport, 
the  exclusion  of  unnecessary  middlemen,  and  the  general 
increase  in  intelligence  and  in  the  efficiency  of  social  organ- 
isation. It  follows  that  the  consumers,  as  consumers,  are 
helpless  in  the  matter.  The  systematic  pressure  upon  the 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  673 

isolated  workman  which  we  have  described  has  reference  to 
them  alone,  and  serves  their  immediate  interests,  but  it  cannot 
be  said  to  be  caused  by  anything  within  their  volition,  or  to 
be  alterable  by  anything  which  they,  in  their  capacity  of 
consumers,  could  possibly  accomplish.1 

Such,  then,  is  the  general  form  of  the  industrial  organisa- 
tion which,  in  so  far  as  it  is  not  tampered  with  by  monopoly 
or  collective  regulation,  grows  up  under  "  the  system  of 
natural  liberty."  The  idea  of  mutual  exchange  of  services 
by  free  and  independent  producers  in  a  state  of  economic 
equality  results,  not  in  a  simple,  but  in  a  highly  complex 
industrial  structure  which,  whether  or  not  consistent  with 
any  real  Liberty,  is  strikingly  lacking  in  either  Equality  or 
Fraternity.  What  is  most  obvious  about  it  is,  not  any 
freedom  in  alternatives  enjoyed  by  the  parties  concerned, 

1  This  analysis  of  the  actual  working  of  the  modern  business  organisation,  with 
its  constant  pressure  on  the  seller,  will  remind  the  economic  student  of  Professor 
Bb'hm-Bawerk's  brilliant  and  suggestive  exposition  of  the  advantage  of  "  present " 
over  "future"  goods.  At  every  stage,  from  the  wage-earner  to  the  shopkeeper, 
it  is  the  compulsion  on  the  seller  to  barter  his  "future  goods"  for  "present 
goods"  which  creates  the  stream  of  pressure.  "  It  is  undeniable,"  says  Professor 
Bohm-Bawerk,  "  that,  in  this  exchange  of  present  commodities  against  future,  the 
circumstances  are  of  such  a  nature  as  to  threaten  the  poor  with  exploitation  of 
monopolists.  Present  goods  are  absolutely  needed  by  everybody  if  people  are  to 
live.  He  who  has  not  got  them  must  try  to  obtain  them  at  any  price.  To  pro- 
duce them  on  his  own  account  is  proscribed  the  poor  man  by  circumstances.  .  .  . 
He  must,  then,  buy  his  present  goods  from  those  who  have  them  ...  by  selling 
his  labor.  But  in  this  bargain  he  is  doubly  handicapped  ;  first,  by  the  position 
of  compulsion  in  which  he  finds  himself,  and  second,  by  the  numerical  relation 
existing  between  buyers  and  sellers  of  present  goods.  The  capitalists  who  have 
present  goods  for  sale  are  relatively  few  ;  the  proletarians  who  must  buy  them 
are  innumerable.  In  the  market  for  present  goods,  then,  a  majority  of  buyers 
who  find  themselves  compelled  to  buy  stands  opposite  a  minority  of  sellers,  and 
this  is  a  relation  which  obviously  is  profoundly  favorable  to  the  sellers  [that  is, 
the  buyers  of  labor  or  wares]  and  unfavorable  to  the  buyers  [that  is,  the  sellers  of 
labor  or  wares],  .  .  .  [This]  may  be  corrected  by  active  competition  among 
sellers  [of  present  goods].  .  .  .  Fortunately,  in  actual  life  this  is  the  rule,  not 
the  exception.  But,  every  now  and  then,  something  will  suspend  the  capitalists' 
competition,  and  then  those  unfortunates,  whom  fate  has  thrown  on  a  local 
market  ruled  by  monopoly,  are  delivered  over  to  the  discretion  of  the  adversary. 
.  .  .  Hence  the  low  wages  forcibly  exploited  from  the  workers — sometimes  the 
workers  of  individual  factories,  sometimes  of  individual  branches  of  production, 
sometimes — though  happily  not  often,  and  only  under  peculiarly  unfavorable 
circumstances — of  whole  nations." — E.  von  Bohm-Bawerk,  The  Positive  Theory 
of  Capital  (London,  1891),  p.  360. 

VOL.  II  2  X 


674  Trade  Union  Theory 

but  the  general  consciousness  of  working  under  pressure 
felt  by  every  class  of  producers.  At  each  link  in  the  chain 
of  bargainings,  the  superiority  in  "  freedom "  is  so  over- 
whelmingly on  the  side  of  the  buyer,  that  the  seller  feels 
only  constraint.1  This  freedom  of  the  purchaser  increases 
with  every  stage  away  from  the  actual  production,  until  it 
culminates  in  the  anarchic  irresponsibility  of  the  private 
customer,  "  free "  alike  from  all  moral  considerations  as  to 
the  conditions  of  employment,  and  from  any  intelligent 
appreciation  of  the  quality  of  the  product.  On  the  other 
hand,  the  impulse  for  cheapness,  of  which  the  consumer  is 
the  unconscious  source,  grows  in  strength  as  it  is  transmitted 
from  one  stage  of  bargaining  to  another,  until  at  last,  with 
all  its  accumulated  weight,  it  settles  like  an  incubus  on  the 
isolated  workman's  means  of  subsistence. 

We  pause  here  for  a  moment,  in  our  analysis  of  the 
industrial  machine,  to  examine  the  case  of  the  domestic 
servant.  The  reader  will  see,  from  this  description  of  the 
higgling  of  the  market,  how  pointless  is  the  statement — 
used  as  a  conclusive  argument  against  the  need  for  Trade 
Unionism,  or  its  power  to  raise  wages — of  the  good  wages 
enjoyed  by  domestic  servants.  There  is  no  analogy  between 
the  engagement  of  domestic  servants  to  minister  to  the 
personal  comfort  of  the  relatively  rich,  and  the  wage-contract 
of  the  operative  employed  by  the  profit-maker.  In  the  first 
place,  the  conditions  of  domestic  service  put  employer  and 

1  The  existence  of  this  feeling  of  constraint  may  be  inferred  from  the  efforts 
which  each  grade  of  producers  makes  to  propitiate  the  buyers.  Every  form  of 
bribery  is  used,  from  the  sweated  outworker's  "tip"  to  the  "giving-out  fore- 
man," the  manufacturer's  Christmas  present  to  the  "buyer"  of  the  wholesale 
house,  the  wholesale  trader's  dinner  to  the  shopkeepers,  and,  finally,  the  cook's 
perquisites  from  the  butcher  and -the  dairyman.  It  is  highly  significant  that  it  is 
always  the  seller  who  bribes,  never  the  buyer.  Sometimes  the  seller's  effort  to 
escape  the  pressure  takes  the  form  of  attempting — usually  by  giving  credit — to 
entangle  the  buyer,  so  as  to  destroy  his  freedom  to  withhold  his  custom  and 
compel  him  to  continue  his  purchases.  Thus,  the  leather-merchant  gives  credit 
to  the  boot-manufacturer,  the  boot-manufacturer  to  the  shopkeeper,  and  the 
shopkeeper  to  the  artisan — the  well-understood  condition  always  being  that  the 
buyer  in  each  case  continues  to  deal  with  the  obliging  seller,  without  too  closely 
scrutinising  his  prices.  We  have  already  mentioned  the  "tallyman,"  who  finds 
his  profit  in  a  similar  entanglement  of  the  necessitous  customer. 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  675 

employed  much  more  on  a  par  with  regard  to  the  bargain 
than  those  of  industrial  wage-labor.  The  alternative  to  the 
well-to-do  woman  of  doing  without  a  servant  for  a  single 
day  is  perhaps  as  disagreeable  to  her  as  the  alternative  to 
the  servant  of  being  out  of  place ;  and  the  worry  and  incon- 
venience to  the  mistress  of  finding  another  servant  is  at  least 
as  great  as  the  discomfort  to  the  servant  of  getting  another 
situation.  In  capacity  of  bargaining  the  servant  is  normally 
as  good  as  the  mistress,  whilst  in  technical  knowledge  she 
is  usually  vastly  superior.  In  the  all-important  matter  of 
carrying  out  the  bargain,  it  is  the  mistress,  with  her  lack  of 
knowledge,  her  indifference  to  details,  and  her  preoccupation 
with  other  affairs,  whose  own  ease  of  body  and  mind  is 
at  the  mercy  of  the  servant's  hundred  and  one  ways  of 
making  herself  disagreeable.  The  personal  comfort  enjoyed 
by  the  servants  in  a  typical  middle-class  household  depends 
mainly  on  themselves  ;  that  of  the  mistress  and  her  family 
depends  to  an  enormous  extent  on  the  goodwill  of  her 
servants.  But  more  important  than  all  these  considerations 
is  the  fact  that  the  conditions  of  employment  of  domestic 
servants  in  middle  or  upper-class  households  are  in  no  way 
affected  by  the  stream  of  competitive  pressure  that  weighs 
down  the  price  of  wares  and  the  wages  of  their  producers. 
As  each  household  works  for  its  own  use,  and  not  for  sale, 
the  temptation  to  "  undercut "  is  entirely  absent.  It  does 
not  make  an  iota  of  difference  to  one  mistress  that  another 
in  the  same  town  pays  lower  wages  to  her  cook  or  her 
housemaid.  Social  pressure  acts,  in  fact,  in  exactly  the 
opposite  direction.  Such  competition  as  exists  between  the 
households  of  the  well-to-do  classes,  whether  in  London  or 
county  society,  or  in  the  more  modest  but  not  less  comfort- 
able professional  or  manufacturers'  "  set "  of  a  provincial 
town,  takes  the  form  of  providing  more  luxurious  quarters 
and  more  perfect  entertainment  for  desirable  guests,  and 
therefore  tends  positively  to  raise  the  wages  spontaneously 
offered  to  clever  and  trustworthy  servants.  Under  these 
circumstances  it  might  have  been  predicted  that  the  rise  in 


676  Trade  Union  Theory 

incomes,  the  greater  desire  for  domestic  comfort,  and  the 
growing  preoccupation  of  upper  and  middle-class  women  in 
other  things  than  housekeeping,  would  have  resulted  in  a 
marked  increase  in  the  wages  of  servants  in  private  house- 
holds.1 So  helpless,  in  fact,  are  the  "  employers "  in  this 
case  that,  if  cooks  and  housemaids  formed  an  effective  Trade 
Union,  so  as  to  use  their  strategic  advantage  to  the  utmost, 
middle-class  women  would  be  forced  to  defend  themselves 
by  taking  refuge  behind  a  salaried  official  or  profit-making 
contractor — for  instance,  by  resorting  to  residential  clubs, 
boarding-houses,  or  co-operatively  managed  blocks  of  flats. 
It  is  noteworthy  that  wherever  the  profit-maker  intervenes, 
the  exceptional  conditions  enjoyed  by  domestic  servants  dis- 
appear. Notwithstanding  the  constant  demand  for  servants 
in  private  households,  the  women  who  cook,  scrub,  clean,  or 
wait  in  the  common  run  of  hotels,  boarding-houses,  lodgings, 
coffee-shops,  or  restaurants,  are  as  ill-paid,  as  ill-treated, 
and  as  overworked  as  their  sisters  in  other  unorganised 
occupations. 

So  far  we  have  mainly  concerned  ourselves  with  tracing 
the  stream  of  pressure  to  its  origin  in  the  private  cus- 
tomer. Now  we  have  to  consider  the  equally  important 
fact  that,  as  each  class  of  producers  becomes  conscious  of 
this  pressure,  it  tries  to  escape  from  it,  to  resist  or  to  evade 
it.  All  along  the  stream  we  discover  the  inhabitants  of  the 
"  debatable  land "  raising  bulwarks  or  dykes,  sometimes 
with  a  view  of  maintaining  quiet  backwaters  of  profit  for 
themselves,  sometimes  with  the  object  of  embanking  their 
Standard  of  Life  against  further  encroachments.  It  is  in 

1  It  is,  we  think,  somewhat  discreditable  to  English  economists  that  they 
should  have  gone  on  copying  and  recopying  from  each  other's  lectures  and  text- 
books the  idea  that  this  rise  in  wages  among  the  domestic  servants  of  the  well- 
to-do  classes  constituted  any  argument  against  the  validity  of  the  case  for  Trade 
Unionism  in  the  world  of  competitive  industry.  We  can  only  attribute  it  to  the 
fact  that  male  economic  lecturers  and  text-book  writers  have  seldom  themselves 
experienced  the  troubles  of  housekeeping,  either  on  a  large  or  on  a  small  scale, 
whilst  the  few  women  economists  have  hitherto  suffered  from  a  lack  of  personal 
knowledge  of  the  actual  relations  between  capitalist  and  workman  in  the  profit- 
making  world. 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  677 

this  deliberate  resistance  to  a  merely  indiscriminate  pressure 
that  we  shall  find,  not  only  the  scope  of  the  Methods  and 
Regulations  of  Trade  Unionism  by  which  certain  sections 
of  the  wage-earners  protect  and  improve  the  conditions  of 
their  employment,  but  also  the  fundamental  reason  for  the 
analogous  devices  of  the  other  producing  classes — the  trade 
secrets,  patents  and  trade  marks,  the  enormous  advertising 
of  specialities,  the  exclusive  franchises  or  concessions,  the 
capitalist  manufacturer's  struggle  to  supersede  the  trader, 
and  the  trader's  backstair  effort  to  do  without  the  capitalist 
manufacturer,  together  with  all  the  desperate  attempts  to 
form  rings  and  trusts,  syndicates  and  "  alliances " — by  one 
or  other  of  which  is  to  be  explained  the  perpetual  inequality 
in  the  profits  of  contemporary  industry,  and  the  heaping  up 
of  fortunes  in  particular  trades.  If  it  were  not  for  this 
deliberate  erection  of  dykes  and  bulwarks  we  should  find,  in 
all  the  old-established  industries,  every  manufacturer  and 
trader  making  only  the  bare  minimum  of  profit,  without 
which  he  would  not  be  induced  to  engage  in  business  at  all, 
and,  we  may  add,  every  wage-earner  reduced  to  bare  sub- 
sistence wages,  below  which  he  could  not  continue  to  exist. 
But  instead  of  this  equality  in  constraint,  with  its  implication 
of  equality  in  minimum  remuneration,  industrial  life  presents, 
and  has  for  over  two  centuries  always  presented,  a  spectacle 
of  extreme  inequality,  alike  between  classes,  trades,  and 
individuals.  We  do  not  here  refer  to  the  differences  of 
remuneration  that  are  commensurate  with  differences  of 
personal  capacity,  whether  physical  or  mental :  these,  like  the 
differences  in  advantageousness  of  different  sites  and  soils, 
with  their  equivalent  differences  of  land  rent,  will,  by  the 
economist,  easily  be  put  on  one  side.  But  it  is  a  matter  of 
common  observation  that  there  are,  at  any  moment,  huge 
incomes  being  gained,  now  in  one  trade,  now  in  another, 
which  bear  no  relation  whatever  to  the  relative  capacity  of 
the  manufacturers  or  traders  concerned,  or  to  the  amount  of 
work  that  they  perform.  To  take  only  this  century,  whilst 
the  brewers  have  always  been  piling  up  riches,  we  see  the 


678  Trade  Union  Theory 

great  fortunes  made  in  cotton  and  other  textiles  a  hundred 
years  ago  succeeded  by  the  fabulous  profits  of  the  coal- 
owners  and  iron-masters,  together  with  those  of  the  machine- 
making  industry  ;  the  great  wealth  amassed  by  the  ship- 
owners and  foreign  merchants  followed  by  the  expansion  of 
the  wholesale  grocers,  the  alkali  producers,  and  the  sewing- 
machine  manufacturers  ;  whilst  to  -  day  huge  gains  are 
admittedly  being  reaped  by  the  wholesale  clothiers  and 
provision  dealers,  the  great  soap  and  pill  advertisers,  and  the 
bicycle  makers.  These  times  of  great  fortunes  may,  as 
regards  any  particular  trade  or  any  particular  firm,  last  only 
a  few  years.  But  the  experience  of  the  last  two  centuries 
furnishes  no  period  in  which  they  did  not  exist  in  one 
quarter  or  another,  and  gives  us  no  warrant  for  assuming 
that  they  will,  under  anything  like  the  existing  order  of 
things,  ever  disappear.  Though  each  particular  case  may 
be  temporary  only,  the  phenomenon  itself  is  of  constant 
occurrence.  From  the  point  of  view  of  the  community  it 
is,  accordingly,  not  evanescent  but  permanent.  It  may,  in 
fact,  be  said  to  be  even  the  most  characteristic  feature  of  the 
present  industrial  system  as  compared  with  any  other,  and 
it  is  one  which  vitally  affects  the  life  of  every  class.  Without 
the  constant  presence  of  these  exceptional  profits  the  indus- 
trial world  would  differ  as  fundamentally  from  that  in  which 
we  now  exist  as  a  Co-operative  Commonwealth  or  a  Socialist 
State.  In  our  view,  they  cannot  be  philosophically  accounted 
for  by  any  reference  to  "  economic  friction "  or  "  lack  of 
mobility "  :  they  are,  as  we  shall  now  attempt  to  show,  the 
direct  and  necessary  consequence,  under  the  "  system  of 
natural  liberty,"  of  the  fact  that  the  stream  of  pressure  that 
we  have  described  impinges,  not  upon  the  normal  weakness 
of  the  isolated  individual  seller,  but  upon  a  series  of  very 
unequal  dykes  and  bulwarks,  cast  up  by  the  different  sections 
of  the  industrial  world.  By  passing  these  briefly  in  review, 
we  shall  be  prepared  to  see,  in  their  due  proportion,  the 
devices  peculiar  to  the  wage-earning  class. 

Let  us  note  first  one  incidental  and  purely  advantageous 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  679 

effect  of  the  constant  pressure  on  all  existing  products  and 
in  all  existing  markets.  It  stimulates  the  capitalist  and 
brainworker  to  desire  to  escape  from  these  closely  swept 
fields,  by  discovering  new  products  or  new  markets.  The 
ever-present  instinct  of  every  manufacturer  or  trader  is  to 
invent  an  article  which  no  rival  yet  produces,  or  to  find 
customers  whom  no  one  yet  serves.  Here  at  last  he  finds  a 
land  of  real  freedom  of  contract,  where  he  has  the  same 
economic  liberty  to  refuse  to  cheapen  his  commodity  as  the 
buyer  has  to  abstain  from  gratifying  that  particular  desire. 
He  cannot,  of  course,  actually  dictate  terms,  for  the  customer 
may  always  prefer  to  go  on  spending  his  income  as  he  has 
hitherto  done.  But  price  is  settled  without  reference  to  fear 
of  competition,  and  is  limited  only  by  the  extent  and  keen- 
ness of  the  demand.  Merely  to  be  first  in  the  field  in  such 
a  case  often  means  a  large  fortune,  which  is  but  the  reward 
for  opening  up  a  fresh  source  of  income  to  producers  and 
of  satisfaction  to  consumers.  But  the  capitalist  is  keenly 
conscious  of  the  completeness  with  which  the  stream  of 
pressure  will  presently  deprive  him  of  this  economic  liberty, 
and  he  therefore  hastens  to  throw  up  a  dyke  before  the 
stream  reaches  him.  Two  hundred  years  ago  he  turned, 
like  the  artisan,  to  the  Government,  and  applied  as  a  matter 
of  course  for  a  charter,  giving  him  royal  authority  to  exclude 
"  interlopers."  When  the  House  of  Commons  took  the  view 
that  there  should  be  "  no  interference  of  the  legislature  with 
the  freedom  of  trade,  or  with  the  right  of  every  man  to 
employ  the  capital  he  inherits,  or  has  acquired,  according  to 
his  own  discretion,"1  it  might  have  been  supposed  that  all 
legal  dykes  and  bulwarks  against  perfect  freedom  of  com- 
petition would  be  brought  to  an  end.  But  though  Parliament 
has  swept  away,  on  this  plea,  every  kind  of  vested  interest 
of  the  artisan,  it  has,  throughout  the  whole  century,  per- 
mitted one  section  of  capitalists  after  another  to  entrench 

1  Report  on  Petitions  of  the  Cotton  Weavers,  1811  ;  Report  of  the  Committee 
on  the  State  of  the  Woollen  Mamifactttre  in  England,  1 806  ;  History  of  Trade 
Unionism,  pp.  54,  56. 


68o  Trade  Union  Theory 

themselves  by  laws  which  excluded  other  capitalists  from 
competing  with  them.  There  has  even  been  lately  a  re- 
crudescence of  Chartered  Companies,  legally  secured  in  the 
enjoyment  of  exceptional  privileges.1  But  apart  from  this 
accidental  result  of  our  growing  Imperialism,  the  century 
has  witnessed  the  building  up  of  an  unparalleled  system  of 
railway,  gas,  water,  and  tramway  monopolies,  founded  on 
private  Acts  of  Parliament.  Here,  it  is  true,  Parliament 
reserves  to  itself  the  right  at  any  time  to  license  another 
competitor.  But  the  policy  throughout  has  been  never  to 
license  a  new  undertaking  in  competition  with  one  already 
in  the  field,  however  profitably  the  business  may  have 
resulted,  unless  the  new  promoters  prove  that  there  is  a 
sufficiently  large  group  or  section  of  customers  who  are  still 
unprovided  with  the  service  in  question.  Thus,  it  is  never 
admitted  even  as  an  argument  in  favor  of  a  proposed  new 
water  company  or  railway,  that  the  one  already  in  the  field 
is  paying  10  per  cent  dividend.  The  new  promoters  do 
not  get  their  Act  unless  they  convince  a  committee  of  each 
House  of  Parliament  that  no  existing  company  is  actually 
supplying  the  service  which  they  desire  to  undertake.  We 
do  not  think  that  people  realise  to  what  an  extent  the 
industrial  wealth  of  the  country  is  invested  in  channels  thus 
legally  safeguarded.  We  roughly  estimate  that,  excluding 
land  and  houses,  something  like  one -fourth  of  the  total 
capital  of  the  United  Kingdom  is  invested  under  private 
Acts  of  Parliament,  and  in  this  way  protected  from  the 
stream  of  competitive  pressure.  It  is  not  merely  that  the 
privileged  capitalists  are  able  to  retain  the  amount  of  custom 
with  which  they  first  started.  They  share  with  the  landlords 

1  The  modern  form  of  charter  carefully  pays  lip-homage  to  "freedom  of 
trade."  But  as  it  usually  gives  the  privileged  adventurers  the  exclusive  ownership 
of  land  and  minerals,  the  right  to  levy  import  and  export  duties  on  all  traders 
(which,  when  the  company  itself  trades,  it  pays  only  from  one  pocket  to  another), 
and  the  power  of  constructing  railways  and  ports  and  of  making  towns  and 
markets,  the  independent  trader  (in  the  Niger  Territories,  for  instance)  or  the 
independent  miner  (in  Rhodesia,  for  instance)  does  not  find  his  position  financially 
so  different  from  that  of  the  eighteenth  -  century  "interloper"  as  might  be 
supposed. 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  68 1 

the  unearned  increment  arising  from  the  mere  growth  of 
population.  They  are  even  protected  against  the  whole 
community  itself,  which  is  not  permitted  co-operatively  to 
provide  its  own  railways  or  water  or  gas,  without  first 
satisfying  the  monopolist  who  is  in  the  field.  We  need  not 
consider  whether  there  was  any  other  way  of  inducing 
capitalists  to  embark  in  these  large,  and,  at  one  time, 
venturesome  undertakings,  otherwise  than  by  thus  according 
them  what  is  virtually  a  legal  guarantee  of  protection  for 
their  "  established  expectation."  But  this  deliberate  Parlia- 
mentary policy  of  creating  and  maintaining  vested  interests 
as  the  best  means  of  securing  the  performance  of  particular 
services — this  virtual  defence  against  the  full  stream  of 
competitive  pressure  enjoyed  by  a  quarter  of  the  whole 
industrial  capital  of  the  community — is  in  itself  an  interest- 
ing criticism  of  "  the  system  of  natural  liberty." 

If  we  pass  now  to  another  incidental  advantage  of  the 
pressure — the  incessant  attempts  of  manufacturers  to  improve 
their  technical  processes — we  shall  find  another  successful 
revolt  against  "  the  system  of  natural  liberty."  If  by  some 
new  invention,  or  new  machine,  the  cost  of  production  can 
be  reduced,  or  a  superior  article  turned  out,  the  manufacturer 
will  be  able  to  yield  to  the  pressure  of  the  wholesale  trader, 
and  yet  make,  at  his  ease,  an  increased  profit  for  himself. 
The  effect  of  the  pressure  would  thus,  it  would  seem,  be  to 
give  the  greatest  possible  stimulus  to  improvements  in 
technical  processes.  But  unless  the  manufacturer  can  erect 
some  kind  of  dyke  for  his  improvement,  so  as  to  prevent  the 
other  manufacturers  from  adopting  the  same  device,  he  will 
very  likely  find  that  the  invention  has  been  a  positive  loss 
to  him  and  them  alike.  For  by  the  time  the  principal 
manufacturers  have  adopted  the  improvement,  no  one  among 
them  is  any  better  able  to  withstand  the  pressure  of  the 
wholesale  trader  than  he  was  before.  The  stream  of 
competition  will  have  swept  away  the  whole  economic 
advantage  of  the  new  invention  by  way  of  reduction  of 
price,  to  the  advantage,  first  of  the  traders,  and  eventually 


682  Trade  Union  Theory 

of  the  customers.  But  this  does  not  complete  the  existing 
manufacturers'  discomfiture.  To  adopt  the  new  invention 
will  have  involved  an  additional  outlay  of  capital,  and  can 
scarcely  fail  to  have  rendered  obsolete,  and  so  destroyed, 
some  portion  of  their  previous  possessions.  Even  at  this 
cost,  the  adaptation  of  the  old  mills  to  the  new  requirements 
leaves  much  to  be  desired  from  the  point  of  view  of  perfect 
economy  of  production.  Here  is  the  chance  for  a  new 
capitalist  to  build  an  entirely  new  mill,  equipped  with  the 
very  latest  improvements,  and  making  the  utmost  of  the  new 
invention.  The  old  manufacturers,  to  whose  ingenuity  and 
enterprise  the  improvement  was  due,  thus  find  themselves, 
under  a  system  of  free  and  unregulated  competition,  placed 
by  it  at  a  positive  disadvantage.  In  this  result  lies  the 
justification  of  the  Patent  Laws,  which  give  the  owner  of  a 
new  invention  a  legal  monopoly  of  its  use  for  a  term  of 
(in  the  United  Kingdom)  fourteen  years.  The  present 
century,  and  especially  the  present  generation,  has  seen  an 
enormous  extension  of  patents  in  every  industry,  it  being 
now  actually  rare  to  find  any  important  manufacturer  who 
does  not  enjoy  one  or  more  of  these  defences  against  com- 
petition. And  though  each  of  them  lasts  only  for  fourteen 
years,  capitalist  ingenuity  has  found  a  way  of  indefinitely 
extending  their  protection.  Before  one  patent  runs  out, 
another  is  secured  for  some  subsidiary  improvement  in  the 
original  invention,  which  the  patentee  has,  of  course,  had  the 
best  opportunity  of  discovering,  or  which  he  has  bought  from 
a  needy  inventor.  The  right  to  manufacture  the  original 
invention  becomes  in  due  course  common  to  all,  but  is  then 
of  little  use  to  anybody,  for  the  legally  protected  monopolist 
of  the  latest  improvement  still  holds  the  field.  No  estimate 
can  be  formed  of  the  amount  of  the  capital  that  is  thus  by 
patents  legally  protected  from  the  pressure  of  free  com- 
petition, but  its  amount  is  enormous  and  daily  increasing. 

We  have  hitherto  dealt  with  the  various  forms  of  legal 
protection  by  which  the  capitalists  have  succeeded  in 
embanking  their  profits  against  the  stream  of  competitive 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  683 

pressure.  We  come  now  to  other  devices  with  the  same 
object.  What  the  manufacturer  seeks  is  in  some  way  to 
escape  from  the  penetrating  pressure  exercised  by  the 
wholesale  trader.  Stimulated  by  the  desire  to  secure 
increased  profits  for  himself,  the  trader  is  always  setting 
his  wits  to  work  to  see  how  he  can  transform  the  blind, 
impartial  pressure  of  the  private  customer  into  a  force  so 
regulated  and  concentrated  as  to  press  always  where  there 
is  least  resistance.  His  specialist  skill  in  bargaining,  his 
trained  appreciation  of  the  minutest  grades  of  quality,  and 
his  quick  apprehension  of  improvements  in  technical  pro- 
cesses, enable  him  so  to  play  off  the  competing  manufacturers 
one  against  the  other,  as  to  make  them  yield  up,  more 
quickly  and  more  completely  than  would  otherwise  have 
been  necessary,  the  exceptional  profits  that  he  discovers  them 
to  be  enjoying.  Thus,  in  the  typically  complete  form  of 
modern  business  organisation,  the  wholesale  and  retail 
traders  act,  virtually,  as  the  expert  agents  of  the  ignorant 
consumer.  The  manufacturers  are  always  seeking  to  relieve 
themselves  of  this  expert  criticism  and  deliberately  adjusted 
pressure  on  the  price  or  quality  of  their  wares,  by  entering 
into  direct  relations  with  the  private  customer.  This  is  the 
economic  explanation  of  the  growth,  during  the  present 
generation,  of  the  world-wide  advertisement  of  distinctive 
specialities,  and  the  consequent  development  of  the  use  of 
trade  marks  or  makers'  names.  If  such  an  impression  can 
be  created  on  the  minds  of  consumers  that  thousands  of  them 
will  insist  on  purchasing  some  particular  article,  the  manu- 
facturer of  that  article  gains  enormously  in  his  strategic 
position  towards  the  wholesale  trader.  It  matters  not  for 
this  purpose  whether  the  consumer's  prejudice  is  or  is  not 
founded  on  proved  excellence  :  many  a  quack  medicine  gives 
as  secure  a  position  of  vantage  as  has  been  won  by  Cadbury's 
Cocoa  or  Dr.  Jaeger's  woollens.  This  enormous  development 
of  "  proprietary  articles,"  beginning  with  patent  medicines, 
but  now  including  almost  every  kind  of  household  requisite, 
has  led  to  an  interesting  form  of  bulwark  against  the 


684  Trade  Union  Theory 

lowering  of  prices.  The  manufacturer  of  a  proprietary 
article  that  has  once  secured  the  favor  of  the  public,  sees 
little  advantage  in  the  cut-throat  competition  which  results 
in  the  customer  getting  it  at  a  lower  price.  He  does  not 
find  that  appreciably  more  of  his  speciality  is  sold  when 
customers  can  buy  it  for  elevenpence  instead  of  thirteen- 
pence-halfpenny.  What  happens,  however,  in  such  a  case 
is  that  the  pressure  on  the  wholesale  trader  to  give  special 
discounts,  or  otherwise  lower  the  wholesale  price,  becomes 
so  irresistible,  that,  presently,  the  wholesale  house  finds  it 
practically  unremunerative  to  deal  in  the  article  at  all,  to 
the  consequent  loss  of  the  manufacturer.  The  enterprising 
proprietor  of  a  distinctive  speciality  therefore  attempts 
nowadays  to  fix  the  price  all  along  the  line.  For  the  pro- 
tection of  all  parties  concerned,  he  devises  what  is  called  an 
"  ironclad  contract."  He  refuses  to  supply,  or  withholds  the 
best  discount  from,  any  wholesale  trader  who  will  not 
formally  bind  himself,  under  penalty,  not  to  sell  below  a 
certain  prescribed  "  wholesale  price."  He  may  even  pre- 
scribe a  definite  retail  price,  below  which  no  shopkeeper  may 
sell  his  wares,  under  penalty  of  finding  the  supply  cut  off. 
Our  own  impression  is  that,  where  the  wholesale  trader  and 
the  retail  shopkeeper  continue  to  be  employed  at  all  in  the 
distribution  of  newly  invented  commodities,  this  strictly 
protected  and  highly  regulated  business  organisation  is 
already  the  typical  form.1 

1  These  "ironclad  contracts"  are  not  easily  seen  by  persons  unconnected 
with  the  particular  trade,  and  we  do  not  believe  that  any  one  has  an  adequate 
idea  of  their  rapid  increase,  or  of  the  enormous  proportion  of  the  total  trade  to 
which  they  now  extend.  We  have  had  the  privilege  of  studying  their  operation 
in  one  of  the  largest  of  English  wholesale  houses,  supplying  household  requisites 
of  every  kind,  and  itself  entering  into  scores  of  contracts  of  this  sort.  We  have 
now  before  us  the  confidential  circulars  of  a  manufacturer  of  well-known 
specialities,  dated  8th  June  1896,  from  which  we  append  some  extracts.  The 
circular  to  retailers,  after  specifying  the  wholesale  prices  and  discounts,  continues  : 
"To  avoid  confusion  of  prices,  and  also  to  prevent  'cutting,'  and  secure  a 
legitimate  profit  for  our  customers,  we  respectfully  require  all  whom  we  supply 
not  to  sell  under  the  prices  named  below.  In  the  interests  of  our  customers, 
therefore,  only  those  will  be  supplied  who  have  signed  an  agreement  to  this  effect." 
The  circular  to  the  wholesale  houses  states  that  there  will  be  paid  "  a  bonus  of 
5  per  cent  conditional  on  goods  not  being  '  cut '  below  our  own  quotations  to  the 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  685 

But  although  the  shopkeeper  prefers  regulation  of  the 
price  of  proprietary  articles  to  the  ruinous  results  of  free 
competition  in  their  sale,  he  greatly  dislikes  proprietary 
articles  altogether.  He  is  always  trying  to  give  a  preference 
to  nondescript  commodities,  of  which  he  can  "  push "  one 
make  rather  than  another,  and  thus  take  advantage  of  the 
customer's  ignorance  to  secure  larger  profits.1  The  manu- 
facturers of  proprietary  articles  retort  by  appointing  their 
own  retail  agents  on  a  definite  commission,  thus  bringing 
into  the  field  the  vast  number  of  bakers  who  sell  packet  tea, 
or  newsvendors  who  push  a  special  brand  of  tobacco.  A 
new  product,  such  as  typewriting  machines  or  bicycles,  will 
break  away  altogether  from  the  typical  business  organisation, 
and  we  see  the  manufacturers  keeping  in  their  own  hands 
both  the  wholesale  and  the  retail  trade,  even  absorbing  also 
the  shipping  business  and  the  repairing.  When  neither 
patent  nor  trademark,  long-standing  reputation  nor  world- 
wide advertisement  can  be  used  as  a  bulwark,  manufacturers 
try  to  protect  themselves  by  rings  and  other  arrangements 
to  fix  prices.  So  obvious  is  the  pecuniary  advantage  of  this 
course,  that  it  is  only  the  long  habits  of  fighting  each  other, 
and  the  mutual  suspicion  thus  engendered,  which  prevent  a 
much  wider  adoption  of  this  expedient  by  English  manu- 
facturers.2 Finally,  we  have  such  bold  attempts  to  abolish 

retail  trade.  .  .  .  This  will  enable  wholesale  houses  ...  to  secure  nearly  14 
per  cent  profit,  and  will,  we  trust,  ensure  your  continual  interest  in  pushing  (the 
article)."  See  also  an  article  on  "Combination  in  Shopkeeping"  in  Progressive 
Review,  April  1897. 

1  It  is  interesting  to  notice,  in  this  connection,  how  willingly  the  Legislature 
has  lent    itself,    by  the  comprehensive  provisions    of   the    Merchandise    Marks 
Acts,  to  the  legal  protection  of  the  security  enjoyed  by  "proprietary  articles" 
against  competition  either  in  price  or  quality.      A  chemist  may  make  "  Condy's 
Fluid"    (the    well-known    disinfecting    solution    of    permanganate    of   potash) 
exactly  in  the  same  way  as  Condy,  cheaper  than  Condy,  and  better  than  Condy, 
but  he  must  not  sell,  under  the  only  name  by  which  customers  will  ask  for  it,  any 
but  the  article  supplied — it  may  be  under  an   "ironclad  contract" — by  Condy 
himself. 

2  We  may  cite  one  of  the  many  informal  and   unknown   "rings,"  which 
dominate    particular    branches    of    manufacture.       The     English    hollow-ware 
trade,    for    instance     (the    manufacture    of    metal    utensils    of    all    kinds)    is 
practically  confined  to  about  a  dozen    firms  in  and  near  Birmingham.     These 
have,  for  many  years,  united  in  fixing  the  prices  of  all  the  articles  they  manu- 


686  Trade  Union  Theory 

competition  altogether,  by  the  union  of  all  rivals  into  a  single 
amalgamation,  as  have  partially  or  wholly  succeeded  in  the 
screw,  cotton-thread,  salt,  alkali,  and  indiarubber  tyre  in- 
dustries in  this  country,  and  in  innumerable  other  cases  in 
the  United  States. 

In  all  the  foregoing  attempts  to  resist  or  evade  the  stream 
of  pressure,  the  device  of  the  capitalist  may  be  regarded  as 
some  form  of  dyke,  tending  to  maintain  prices  at  a  paying 
level.  In  other  cases  we  see  a  different  expedient.  We 
have  already  noticed  the  fact  that,  when  a  new  industry 
springs  up,  there  is  nowadays  a  tendency  to  prevent  any 
differentiation  of  productive  structure,  and  to  retain  all  the 
grades  in  a  single  hand.  Thus  the  typewriter  and  bicycle 
manufacturers,  following  in  the  wake  of  the  great  sewing- 
machine  producers,  eliminate  all  the  traders.  But  the 
telescoping  may  start  also  from  the  other  end.  Out  of  the 
village  pedlar  in  the  country,  or  the  little  town  retailer  of 
cheap  boots  and  clothes,  has  grown  the  colossal  wholesale 
clothier  of  our  day,  who  gives  out  work  to  thousands  of 
isolated  families  all  over  the  country  ;  sorts  and  labels  in 
his  warehouse  their  diverse  products  ;  supplies  his  own  retail 
shops  in  the  different  towns  ;  executes  asylum  and  workhouse 
contracts  ;  and  ships,  on  his  own  account,  to  Cape  Town  or 
Melbourne,  the  hundreds  of  thousands  of  "  cheap  suits " 
annually  absorbed  by  the  Colonies.  Here  the  characteristic 
feature  is  not  the  keeping  up  of  the  price  against  the  con- 
sumer, but  an  exceptionally  terrible  engine  of  oppression  of 
the  manual-working  producer.  In  all  the  "  sweated  in- 
dustries," in  fact,  the  capitalist's  expedient  is  not  to  evade 
the  pressure  for  cheapness,  but  to  find  a  means  of  making 
that  pressure  fall  with  all  its  weight  on  the  worker.  We 
have  already  described  the  disadvantageous  position  of 

facture.  A  uniform  wholesale  price-list  is  agreed  upon,  with  three  different 
rates  of  discount.  The  firms  are  classified  by  common  consent,  according  to  the 
perfection  of  finish  of  their  wares  and  the  prestige  which  they  enjoy,  into  three 
grades,  each  adhering  to  its  corresponding  rate  of  discount.  This  "ring"  is 
quite  informal,  but  has  for  years  been  well  maintained  to  the  apparent  satisfac 
tion  of  its  members. 


The  Htggling  of  tke  Market  6o7 

the  isolated  workman  when  hP  h 

™li  or  a  factory.      But  he  has   7T*  *'*  **  °W™  of  a 
of  knowing  what  the  other  woricm       7  '**'  the  advantage 
valuable  moral  support  which  crT"  T  ^  Md  the  '""- 
sh-P  of  number,  ^OreoVer   as Te'h      "  ^  C°mpanio"- 
factones,  the  Trade   Union   Method     TiT"'  '"  mills  ™* 
Collective  Bargaining,  and  VJ ^  h°ds  °f  Mutual   Insurance, 
the  form  of  Common  Rule,  th        Enactme"t  erect  dykes  in 
shall  presently  discuss     BuUhe  hrr0"1^6^15  °f  Which  « 
these  protections,  and  finds  himtl?Tr  ^  W1'th°Ut  any  °f 
barest  subsistence  wage      AnH     u  ed)  as  a  rule'  to  the 

t-de,  these  home-woTkers ^  ^  "  Jn  the  -I^othlnJ 
-thout  any  notion  of  a  definite  "t  ^  ^  das^ 
Polish  Jews  and  unskilled  En",?,  "^  °f  Life"-for 
at.  any  price(  under  ^  hwomen .will  do  any  work, 

dnven  even  below  what^o^d  £0 Th     '[  "^  wi"    b<= 
«   working  efficiency.       Thus    in    ^  &SS  Pe™anently 

Astern  "the  capita,/t  em  ^  ln    the  so-ca]led    ,Sw         ^ 

°f  evading  the  downward  Sure    \    u^  3  Way'  not  °4 
retail  trader  normally  exeSS  ,  ?  the  Wholesale  a"d 

also  of  escaping  the  SjESff  f       T"6**1"*'  but 
regulat,on  by  which  the  facto™  of  co«bination  or  legal 

Standard  of  Life  now  usuallvTn  T"  ^''^  to  ^duce  the 
colossal  fortunes  which  hT^  £?  h™SeIf  C°nfr°nted-  The 
^  the  wholesale  clothi^^' ^  areksti»  being,  made 
small  section  of  capitalists  of  I  C  absorPt;on,  by  one 

debatable  land  lying"  b e^n   ^      *  V^  Wh°'e  °f  *a 
sumer  lgnorant  ^          ee"  the  pr         hat  a  carelgss  ^ 

the  industry,  will  continuqe  ^  ^  <*  the  transformation  of 
subsid.sed  women  and  a  stream  /  &  *"  Wa&e  tha'  half- 
lands  will  continue  to  accent 7 /  °utCaSt  Jews  from  °ther 
altogether.  ^  raAer  than  forego  employment 

dtictly  "wh^         bn'e%  ind/Cated  -me 


688  Trade  Union  Theory 

formed  and  irresponsible  consumers  are  always  unconscien- 
tiously  exercising.  To  analyse  adequately  these  various 
expedients,  to  discuss  how  far  they  increase  or  diminish  the 
wealth  of  nations,  to  discover  how  they  affect  national 
character  or  are  consistent  with  this  or  that  view  of  social 
expediency,  would  require  as  detailed  an  investigation  of  the 
actual  facts  of  business  organisation  as  we  have  undertaken 
with  regard  to  Trade  Unionism.  Such  an  investigation 
would,  we  believe,  yield  results  of  the  utmost  value  to  the 
community.  One  thing  is  clear.  Those  capitalist  dykes 
and  bulwarks,  short  cuts  and  artificial  floodings,  have  become 
so  constant  and  general  a  feature  of  the  whole  "  debatable 
land  "  of  economic  bargaining,  that  any  discussion  of  the  re- 
lation between  consumer  and  producer,  or  between  capitalist, 
brain-worker,  and  manual  laborer,  which  is  based  on  the 
assumption  of  a  mutual  exchange  of  services  among  freely 
competing  individual  bargainers,  is,  from  a  practical  point  of 
view,  entirely  obsolete.  We  have,  in  fact,  to  work  out  a  new 
scientific  analysis,  not  of  any  ideal  state  of  "  natural  liberty," 
but  of  the  actual  facts  of  a  world  of  more  or  less  complete 
economic  monopolies — legal  monopolies,  natural  mono- 
polies, monopolies  arising  out  of  exploiting  the  prejudices  of 
consumers,  and,  last  but  not  least,  monopolies  deliberately 
constructed  by  the  tacit  or  formal  combination  or  amalgama- 
tion of  all  the  competing  interests.1  But  before  passing 
away  from  this,  by  the  economist,  as  yet  unexplored  world, 

1  In  the  Groundwork  of  Economic ~s,  sec.  20,  p.  33  (London,  1883),  Mr.  C. 
S.  Devas  reminds  us  that,  "  in  a  wise  moment,1'  J.  S.  Mill  objected  to  the  abstract 
methods  of  his  father,  and  the  other  economic  politicians  of  that  school.  "It  is 
not  to  be  imagined  possible,"  Mill  said,  "  nor  is  it  true  in  point  of  fact,  that  these 
philosophers  regarded  the  few  premises  of  their  theory  as  including  all  that  is 
required  for  explaining  social  phenomena.  .  .  .  They  would  have  applied,  and  did 
apply,  their  principles  with  innumerable  allowances.  But  it  is  not  allowances 
that  are  wanted.  ...  It  is  unphilosophical  to  construct  a  science  out  of  a  few 
agencies  by  which  the  phenomena  are  determined.  .  .  .  We  ought  to  study  all 
the  determining  agencies  equally \  and  endeavor,  as  far  as  it  can  be  done,  to  in- 
clude all  of  them  -within  the  pale  of  the  science,  else  we  shall  infallibly  bestow  a 
disproportionate  attention  upon  those  which  our  theory  takes  into  account,  while 
we  misestimate  the  rest,  and  probably  underrate  their  importance."  The  quotation 
is  from  Mill's  System  of  Logic,  Book  VI.,  end  of  chap.  viii. 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  689 

we    are   compelled    to   note  how   it  impinges   on    our   own 
province.1 

In  our  analysis  of  the  chain  of  bargainings  which  take 
place  between  the  manual  worker  and  the  private  customer, 
and  so  determine  the  wages  of  labor,  we  demonstrated,  not 
only  that  the  isolated  individual  workman  was  at  a  serious 
disadvantage  in  bargaining  with  the  capitalist  manufacturer, 
but  also  that  the  capitalist  manufacturer  himself  was  to  a 
large  extent  powerless  to  offer  terms  above  those  prevailing 
in  other  establishments.  But  this  latter  consideration,  as  we 
now  see,  does  not  necessarily  apply  to  any  but  those  cases 
in  which  there  has  been  no  obstruction  of  the  full  stream  of 
competitive  pressure.  If  an  individual  employer  is  able  to 
ward  off  this  pressure  from  the  price  of  his  product  by  an 
exclusive  concession  or  a  patent,  a  trade  mark,  or  even  an 
assured  personal  connection,  or  if  the  whole  body  of 
employers  can  unite  in  a  tacit  or  formal  combination  to 

1  These  monopolies,  it  will  be  observed,  are,  to  a  large  extent,  actually  the 
outcome  of  legal  freedom  of  contract.  If  every  man  is  to  be  free  to  enter  into 
such  contracts  as  seem  to  him  best  in  his  own  interest,  it  is  impossible  to  deny 
him  the  right  of  joining  with  his  fellow-capitalists  to  fix  prices,  regulate  produc- 
tion, or  actually  to  amalgamate  all  competing  interests,  if  this  is  deemed  most 
advantageous.  "  Monopoly,  "says  Professor  Foxwell,  "  is  inevitable.  .  .  It  is  a 
natural  outgrowth  of  industrial  freedom"  ("The  Growth  of  Monopoly,  and  its 
Bearing  on  the  Functions  of  the  State,"  in  JRcvue  cT  Economic  Politique,  vol.  iii. 
September  1889).  That  this  state  of  things  involves  the  economic  compulsion  of 
minorities,  the  ruin  of  newcomers  by  deliberate  underselling,  and  the  driving  out 
of  the  trade  of  any  recalcitrant  firm,  is,  as  Mr.  Justice  Chitty  lucidly  explained  in 
the  case  of  the  Mogul  Steamship  Co.  v.  Macgregor,  Gow,  and  Co.,  an  inevitable 
result  of  legal  freedom  of  contract.  The  classic  economists  never  made  up  their 
minds  whether,  by  a  "system  of  natural  liberty,"  they  meant  individual  freedom 
of  contract,  or  free  competition  between  individuals.  As  we  have  already 
explained  in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining,"  these  two 
social  ideals  are  not  only  not  identical,  but  hopelessly  inconsistent  with  each 
other.  Alike  in  the  world  of  capital  and  in  the  world  of  labor,  individual  freedom 
of  contract  leads  inevitably  to  combination,  and  this  destroys  free  competition 
between  individuals.  If  we  desire  to  maintain  free  competition  between  indi- 
viduals, the  only  conceivable  way  would  be  such  a  state  interference  with  con- 
tracts as  would  prevent,  not  only  every  kind  of  association,  but  also  every  aliena- 
tion of  land  and  every  transfer  of  small  businesses  to  larger  ones,  which  would 
in  any  way  cause  or  increase  inequality  of  wealth  or  power.  Indeed,  it  would 
be  an  interesting  point  for  academic  discussion  whether  free  competition  among 
equal  units,  supposing  this  to  be  desired  and  to  be  compatible  with  human  nature, 
can  be  permanently  secured  in  any  other  way  than  by  the  "  nationalisation  of  the 
means  of  production,  distribution,  and  exchange." 

VOL.  II  2  Y 


690  Trade  Union  Theory 

regulate  the  trade,  the  workpeople  in  these  establishments 
might,  it  may  be  argued,  stand  some  chance  of  receiving 
better  wages.  And  in  so  far  as  these  partial  monopolies  are 
directed  by  public-spirited  philanthropists, — so  long,  too,  as  the 
exceptional  profits  remain  in  the  hands  of  the  original  capital- 
ists,— this  presumption  is  borne  out  by  facts.  Such  well- 
known  firms  as  Cadbury,  Horrocks,  Tangye,  and  a  host  of 
other  manufacturers  of  specialities,  are  noted  for  being 
"  good  employers,"  that  is,  for  voluntarily  conceding  to  each 
grade  of  labor  better  terms  than  similar  workers  obtain  in 
other  establishments.  But  in  this  connection  it  is  important 
to  remember  that  the  standard  by  which  the  "good  employer" 
determines  the  conditions  of  labor  is  not  any  deliberate  view 
of  what  is  required  for  full  family  efficiency  and  worthy 
citizenship,  but  a  practical  estimate  of  what  each  grade  of 
workers  would  obtain  from  the  ordinary  employer,  working 
under  competitive  pressure.  Hence  a  comparatively  small 
addition  to  weekly  wages,  a  more  equitable  piecework  list, 
a  larger  degree  of  consideration  in  fixing  the  hours  for 
beginning  or  quitting  work,  the  intervals  for  meals  and  the 
arrangements  for  holidays,  greater  care  in  providing  the  little 
comforts  of  the  factory,  or  in  rendering  impossible  the  petty 
tyrannies  of  foremen, — any  of  these  ameliorations  of  the  con- 
ditions of  labor  will  suffice,  without  serious  inroads  on  profits, 
to  attract  to  a  firm  the  best  workers  in  the  town,  to  gain  for 
it  a  reputation  for  justice  and  benevolence,  and  to  give  the 
employer's  family  an  abiding  sense  of  satisfaction  whenever 
they  enter  the  works,  or  cross  the  thresholds  of  their  opera- 
tives' homes.  To  this  extent  it  is  true  that  "the  strength 
of  the  capitalist  is  the  shield  of  the  laborer."1  But  this 
relatively  humane  relationship  is  nowadays  seldom  of  long 
standing.  If  the  business  grows  to  any  size  it  will  very 
soon  be  formed  into  a  joint-stock  company,  in  which  the  old 
partners  may  at  first  retain  a  large  interest,  but  of  which  a 
yearly  increasing  proportion  is  transferred  to.  outside  share- 
holders. These  new  shareholders,  who  will  have  bought  in 

1   Trade  Unionism,  by  James  Stirling  (Glasgow,  1869),  p.  42. 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  691 

at  a  price  yielding  them  no  more  than  the  current  rate  of 
interest  for  that  class  of  security,  feel  that  they  have  no 
margin  of  exceptional  profit  to  dispose  of.  Even  if  the  old 
partners'  families  retain  large  holdings  in  their  ancestral 
concern,  they  have,  by  capitalising  their  profits,  lost  their 
privilege  of  being  benevolent  with  them  ;  and  the  share- 
holders' meeting,  the  board  of  directors,  and  the  salaried 
general  manager  inevitably  bring  in  "  business  principles," 
and  pay  no  more  for  labor  than  they  are  compelled.  And 
when  we  pass  to  the  gigantic  capitalist  corporations,  admin- 
istering legal  monopolies,  or  to  the  colossal  amalgamations 
more  and  more  dominating  the  industrial  world,  we  find,  in 
sharpest  contrast  with  the  patriarchal  employer  of  economic 
romance,  the  daily  changing  crowd  of  share  and  debenture 
owners,  devoid  of  any  responsibility  for  the  conditions  of 
labor,  and  as  uninformed  and  heedless  as  the  consumer  him- 
self. It  is  not  too  much  to  say  that,  so  far  as  concerns  the 
personal  life  of  the  50,000  employees  of  the  London  and 
North  -  Western  Railway  Company,  the  55,000  ordinary 
shareholders,  who  own  that  vast  enterprise,  are  even  more 
ignorant,  more  inaccessible,  and  more  irresponsible  than  the 
millions  of  passengers  whom  they  serve.  The .  situation 
is  intensified  by  the  fact  that,  in  the  absence  of  law  or 
Collective  Bargaining,  these  great  capitalist  monopolies  can 
practically  dictate  their  own  terms  to  their  workpeople.  If,  as 
is  now  admitted,  the  isolated  workman  stands  at  a  serious 
disadvantage  in  bargaining  with  the  capitalist  manufacturer, 
what  shall  we  say  of  the  position  of  the  candidate  who 
applies  for  the  situation  of  porter  or  shunter  to  the  officer 
of  a  great  railway  company  ?  Here  the  very  notion  of 
bargaining  disappears.  This  does  not  mean  that  such 
capitalists  will  necessarily  dictate  the  absolute  minimum 
wage.  The  corporation  decides,  in  its  own  interest,  what 
policy  it  will  pursue  as  regards  wages,  hours,  and  other  con- 
ditions. Porters  and  shunters,  plate-layers  and  general 
laborers,  can  be  had  practically  in  any  number  at  any  price. 
Whether  it  pays  best  to  give  the  lowest  wage  on  which  the 


692  Trade  Union  Theory 

human  animal  can  temporarily  subsist,  and  be  content  with 
a  low  level  of  muscular  endurance,  or  whether  it  is  better  to 
pay  for  superior  men,  and  work  them  for  ninety  hours  a 
week,  is  a  question  which,  in  the  absence  of  any  interference 
with  "  freedom  of  contract,"  is  settled  on  much  the  same 
principles  as  actuate  a  tramway  company,  deciding  whether 
it  is  more  profitable  to  wear  its  horses  out  in  four  years  or 
in  seven.  And  once  the  worker  enters  the  employment  of 
any  of  these  gigantic  monopolists,  the  alternative  to  submis- 
sion to  his  employer's  commands  is,  not  merely  changing  his 
situation,  but  finding  some  new  means  of  livelihood.  For  a 
railway  servant  who  leaves  without  a  character,  or  with  a 
black  mark  against  his  name,  knows  perfectly  well  that  he 
will  seek  a  situation  in  vain  from  any  other  railway  company 
in  the  kingdom.  Thus  it  is  only  in  exceptional  instances, 
and  then  only  temporarily,  that  the  wage-earners  as  a  class 
get  any  share  of  the  extra  profits  secured  to  the  capitalists 
by  their  dykes  and  bulwarks.  These  exceptional  profits  are 
quickly  capitalised  by  their  owners,  and  transferred  to  new 
shareholders  who  come  in  at  a  premium.  The  more  com- 
plete and  legally  secured  is  the  monopoly,  the  more  certain 
it  is  to  be  disposed  of  at  a  price  which  yields  only  a  low 
rate  of  interest — in  extreme  cases,  such  as  urban  waterworks, 
approximating  actually  to  the  return  on  government  secur- 
ities themselves.  On  the  other  hand,  the  position  of  the 
wage-earner  is  positively  worsened,  in  the  colossal  capitalist 
corporations,  by  the  absence  of  effective  competition  for  his 
services  by  rival  employers.  The  difference  in  strategic 
position  becomes  so  overwhelming  that  the  wage-contract 
ceases  to  be,  in  any  genuine  sense,  a  bargain  at  all.1 

Amid  all  the  capitalist  devices  that  we  have  described, 
the  workmen's  efforts  to  protect  themselves  against  the  full 

1  ' '  To  assume  that  the  competition  between  the  employer  on  the  one  hand,  and 
the  wage-earners  on  the  other,  when  the  latter  are  unorganised  and  unprotected 
by  law,  is  a  competition  between  equal  units,  is  so  fanciful  and  contrary  to  fact, 
that  any  conclusions  drawn  from  such  an  assumption  can  have  little  value  under 
present  circumstances." — B.  R.  Wise,  Indtistrial  Freedom  (London,  1892), 
pp.  13,  15. 


The  HiggHng  of  the  Market 


—  co,nparativel 

things,   no    section    of  w          ^  Capitalist   u"^r- 

secure  from  Par]iament  he  ^e-Jar"e«  can  nowadays 
certa,n  service.  Unlike  tZ  XC'USIve  "S**  to  perform  a 
"-chine,  a  workrnan  ^  ~  .<*  a  newly-invented 

-ost  ingenious  imp  ™  .Ten      wV  '^  ™"°P°>y  of 
share  of  the  productive  pr^ffo  ^  may  make  »  his 
tent  to  the  inventor  of  a  new  trict    f°  C°Untry  gra"ts  a 
Perhaps  only   a  nove]     V^T  ™*  of  manual  dexterity 

enormously  increases  ^  pSJ^f  ^  fi^ers—  Wch 
even  the  most  ski,,ed  J^"!^  of  '"dusby.     Nor  can 
h'mself,  like  the  adverfeer  of  l*b°Kr  m™  time  assure  to 
secured  tr.de  mark,  the  faithful      T^'*'  °r  °f  a   Iegally 
Astant  private   consumers      And^h     f  °f  *  iarge  ^  « 
earners  form  the  base  of  thetdu  I     ,    *  that  the  w^- 
»«>   -eaker  c,ass    be]ow   ^  w±^  Pyramid'  and  have 
Pressure,  shuts  them  out  from  «  ^       7  Ca"    transfer 
as  we  have  seen  to  profi    S^JJ*  f  aS;°"S  °f  the 
dykes  and   bulwarks  C'°thier-     A) 


from  becoming  even  aT  l°  Prevented  such  «a«  pe™anently  impossible 

wi»  be  found  SsJT-tant  Part  of  ^e  fiSish  ?!OClatlon.s  ^Producers" 
Condon,  first  edition  18  '"  ^  ^^^"^^^^  Movement_ 
Sldney  Webb).  W  second  edition 


694  Trade  Union  Theory 

industrial  field,  the  wage-earners  cling  with  stubborn  obstinacy 
to  certain  customary  standards  of  expenditure.  However 
overpowering  may  be  the  strategic  strength  of  the  employer, 
however  unorganised  and  resourceless  may  be  the  wage- 
earners,  it  is  found  to  be  impossible  to  reduce  the  wages  and 
other  conditions  of  particular  grades  of  workmen  below  a 
certain  vaguely  defined  standard.  In  the  years  of  worst 
trade,  when  thousands  of  engineers  or  boilermakers,  masons 
or  plumbers,  are  walking  the  streets  in  search  of  work,  the 
most  grasping  employer  knows  that  it  is  useless  for  him  to 
offer  them  work  in  their  respective  trades  at  ten  or  fifteen 
shillings  a  week.  Sooner  than  suffer  such  violence  to  their 
feelings  of  what  is  fit  and  becoming  to  their  social  position, 
they  will  work  as  unskilled  laborers,  or  pick  up  odd  jobs, 
for  the  same,  or  even  lower  earnings  than  they  refuse  as 
craftsmen.  This  stubborn  refusal  to  render  their  particular 
class  of  service  for  a  wage  that  strikes  them  as  outrageously 
below  their  customary  standard,  does  not  depend  on  their 
belonging  to  a  Trade  Union,  for  it  is  characteristic  of 
unionists  and  non-unionists  alike,  and  is  found  in  trades  in 
which  no  combination  exists.  Even  the  dock-laborer,  who 
frantically  struggles  at  the  dock-gates  for  any  kind  of  employ- 
ment, turns  sulky,  and  discharges  himself  after  a  few  hours, 
if  he  is  asked  to  work  for  a  shilling  a  day.  Nor  does  it 
apply  only  to  money  wages.  The  British  workman  in  the 
building  trades,  though  he  is  paid  by  the  hour,  and  often 
belongs  to  no  union,  will  accept  any  alternative  rather  than 
let  his  employer  keep  him  habitually  at  work  for  fifteen 
hours  a  day.  Nor  has  this  conventional  minimum  any 
assignable  relation  to  the  cost  of  actual  subsistence.  The 
young  engineer  or  plumber,  unencumbered  by  wife  or  child, 
indignantly  refuses  to  work  for  a  wage  upon  which  millions 
of  his  fellow-citizens  not  only  exist,  but  marry  and  bring  up 
families.  On  the  other  hand,  though  the  London  dock- 
laborer  will  not  go  on  working  at  a  shilling  a  day,  he 
willingly  accepts  irregular  work  at  a  rate  per  hour  which, 
taking  into  account  the  periods  of  unemployment  incidental 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  695 

to  his  occupation,  is  demonstrably  insufficient  for  sustained 
physical  health  or  industrial  efficiency.  This  practical  check 
on  the  employer's  power  of  reducing  wages  has  always  been 
observed  by  the  economists.  "  Where,"  observed  J.  S.  Mill, 
"  there  is  not  in  the  people,  or  in  some  very  large  proportion 
of  them,  a  resolute  resistance  to  this  deterioration — a  deter- 
mination to  preserve  an  established  standard  of  comfort — 
the  condition  of  the  poorest  class  sinks,  even  in  a  progressive 
state,  to  the  lowest  point  which  they  will  consent  to  endure."  * 
The  classic  economists  were  especially  struck  by  the  way  in 
which  this  determination  to  preserve  an  established  standard 
of  comfort  affected  the  level  of  wages  in  different  countries, 
and  among  different  districts  or  races  in  the  same  country.2 
"  Custom,"  said  Adam  Smith,  ..."  has  rendered  leather 
shoes  a  necessary  of  life  in  England.  The  poorest  creditable 
person  of  either  sex  would  be  ashamed  to  appear  in  public 
without  them.  In  Scotland,  custom  has  rendered  them  a 
necessary  of  life  to  the  lowest  order  of  men,  but  not  to  the 
same  order  of  women,  who  may,  without  any  discredit,  walk 
about  barefooted.  In  France  they  are  necessaries  neither 
to  men  nor  to  women." a  "  The  circumstances  and  habits  of 

1  J.  S.  Mill,  Principles  of  Political  Economy ,  Book  IV.  chap.  vi.  §  I,  p.  453. 
"The  habitual   earnings   of   the  working  classes  at   large  can  be  affected    by 
nothing  but  the  habitual  requirements  of  the  laboring  people  ;  these,  indeed, 
may  be  altered,  but  while  they  remain  the  same  wages  never  fall  permanently 
below  the  standard  of  these  requirements  and  do  not  long  remain  above  that 
standard." — Ibid.  Book  V.  chap.  x.  §  5,  p.  564. 

2  "  In  England,  for  example,  the  lower  classes  principally  live  on  wheaten 
bread  and  butcher's  meat,  in  Ireland  on  potatoes,  and  in  China  and  Hindostan 
on  rice.      In  many  provinces  of  France  and  Spain  an  allowance  of  wine  is  con- 
sidered indispensable.      In  England  the  laboring  class  entertain  nearly  the  same 
opinion  with  respect  to  porter,  beer,  and  cider  ;  whereas  the  Chinese  and  Hindoos 
drink  only  water.     The  peasantry  of  Ireland  live  in  miserable  mud-cabins  without 
either  a  window  or  a  chimney,  or  anything  that  can  be  called  furniture  ;  while  in 
England  the  cottages  of  the  peasantry  have  glass  windows  and  chimneys,  are  well 
furnished,  and  are  as  much  distinguished  for  their  neatness,  cleanliness,  and  com- 
fort, as  those  of  the  Irish  for  their  filth  and  misery.      These  differences  in  their 
manner  of  living  occasion  equal  differences  in  their  wages ;  so  that,   while  the 
average  price  of  a  day's  labor  may  be  taken  at  from  2od.  to  2s.,  it  cannot  be 
taken  at  more  than  ;d.   in  Ireland,  and  3d.  in  Hindostan." — J.  R.  M'Culloch, 
A  Treatise  on  the  Circumstances  which  determine  the  Kate  of  Wages  (London, 
1851),  p.  32. 

3  Wealth  of  Nations,  Book  V.  chap.  ii.  art.  iv.  p.  393. 


696  Trade  Union  Theory 

living  prevalent  in  England,"  wrote  Colonel  Torrens,  "  have 
long  determined  that  women  in  the  laboring  classes  shall 
wear  their  feet  and  legs  covered,  and  eat  wheaten  bread,  with 
a  portion  of  animal  food.  Now,  long  before  the  rate  of 
wages  could  be  so  reduced  as  to  compel  women  in  this  part 
of  the  United  Kingdom  to  go  with  their  legs  and  feet  un- 
covered, and  to  subsist  upon  potatoes,  with  perhaps  a  little 
milk  from  which  the  butter  had  been  taken,  all  the  labor- 
ing classes  would  be  upon  parochial  relief,  and  the  land  in 
a  great  measure  depopulated."  l  "  These  differences  in  their 
manner  of  living,"  summed  up  M'Culloch,  "  occasion  equal 
differences  in  their  wages."  But  whilst  the  fact  was  clearly 
recognised,  no  satisfactory  explanation  of  it  was  given.  The 
only  reason  for  these  differences  in  wages  that  the  classic 
economists  could  allege  was  that  the  customary  "  standard 
of  comfort"  determined  the  rate  at  which  the  population 
would  increase — that  any  attempt  by  the  employer  to  reduce 
wages  below  this  level  would  promptly  cause  fewer  children 
to  be  born,  and  thus  alter  the  ratio  of  workers  to  wage-fund 
twenty  years  hence  ! 2  But  this,  it  is  obvious,  does  not  tell 
us  why  it  is  that  the  workman  is  able  to  refuse  to  accept 
less  to-day,  even  if  population  statistics  still  allowed  us  to 
make  any  such  assumption  about  the  birth-rate.  If  the 
economists  had  not  been  obsessed  by  the  fallacy  of  a  pre- 
determined wage-fund,  they  would  have  perceived,  in  this 
clinging  of  each  generation  to  its  accustomed  livelihood,  a 
primitive  bulwark  against  the  innovation  of  fixing  all  the 
conditions  of  labor  by  "  free  competition  "  among  candidates 
for  employment.  To  the  modern  observer  it  is  obvious  that 

1  Essay  on  the  External  Corn   Trade,  by  Robert  Torrens  (London,  1815), 
p.   58.      See  other  references  in  Gunton's    Wealth  and  Progress  (London,  1888), 

P-  193- 

2  "  Even  though  wages  were  high  enough  to  admit  of  food's  becoming  more 
costly  without  depriving  the  laborers  and  their  families  of  necessaries  ;  though 
they  could  bear,   physically  speaking,  to  be  worse  off,  perhaps  they  would  not 
consent  to  be  so.      They  might  have  habits  of  comfort  which  were  to  them  as 
necessaries,  and  sooner  than  forego  which  they  would  put  an  additional  restraint 
on  their  power  of  multiplication,  so  that  wages  would  rise,  not  by  increase  of 
deaths  but  by  diminution  of  births." — J.  S.  Mill,  Principles  of  Political  Economy, 
Book  II.  chap.  xi.  §  2,  p.  209  (London,  1865). 


7^ he  Higgling  of  the  Market  697 

the  existence,  among  all  the  workmen  of  a  particular  grade, 
of  an  identical  notion  as  to  what  amount  and  kind  of  weekly 
expenditure  constitutes  snhsisfrenre,  Js  in  itself  equivalent-  *o- 
a  tacit  combination.  It  is,  in  fact,  however  it  may  have 
come  about,  an  incipient  Common  Rule,  supported  by  a 
universal  and  prolonged  refusal  to  work,  which  is  none  the 
less  a  strike"in  that  it'Ts^unconcerted'anorUnHeliberate.  If 
every  artisan,  without  the  slightest  concert  with  his  fellows, 
is  possessed  by  an  unreasoning  prejudice  that  he  and  his 
family  must  consume  wheaten  bread,  butcher's  meat,  beer, 
and  tea,  instead  of  living  on  oatmeal,  maize,  potatoes,  and 
water,  the  employer  will  find  it  useless  to  suggest  that  "  any 
meal  is  better  than  none."  He  quickly  discovers  that  if  he 
offers  wages  which  will  provide  only  the  cheaper  food,  no 
individual  of  the  class  that  he  requires  will  accept  his  situa- 
tion. He  is,  in  fact,  face  to  face  with  what  is  virtually  a 
universal  strike.  Like  all  other  strikes  it  may,  for  one  reason 
or  another,  presently  fail.  But  as  long  as  it  lasts  the  alter- 
native to  the  employer  of  coming  to  terms  with  the  work- 
man is,  not  one  man's  absence  from  his  usual  staff,  but 
getting  no  men  at  all — not  foregoing  a  fraction  of  his  profits, 
but  shutting  up  his  establishment.  It  is  accordingly  plain 
that,  in  a  class  of  workmen  among  whom  any  such  identical 
notion  as  to  the  Standard  of  Comfort  exists,  the  isolated 
individual  wage-earner  bargains  at  greater  advantage  than 
he  would  if  he  and  his  fellows  were  willing  to  accept  any 
kind  of  wages  rather  than  none.  The  mere  existence,  among 
all  the  workmen  competing  for  a  certain  class  of  employment, 
of  an  identical  notion  as  to  what  constitutes  their  minimum 
subsistence,  amounts,  therefore,  even  without  concert  or  reserve- 
fund,  to  a  real  bulwark  against  the  pressure  of  competition.1 

1  We  are  unable  here  to  do  more  than  refer  to  the  existence  of  these  popular 
ideas  as  to  the  Standard  of  Life.  How  they  originate — why,  for  instance,  the 
English  workman  should  always  have  insisted  on  eating  costly  and  unnutritious 
wheaten  bread,  or  why  some  classes  or  races  display  so  much  more  stubbornness 
of  standard  than  others,  would  be  a  fruitful  subject  for  economic  inquiry.  We 
suggest,  as  a  hypothetical  classification  by  way  of  starting-point,  that  the  races 
and  classes  of  wage-earners  seem  to  divide  themselves  into  three  groups.  There 
are  those  who,  like  the  Anglo-Saxon  skilled  artisan,  will  not  work  below  a 


698  Trade  Union  Theory 

But  this  primitive  bulwark — the  instinctive  Standard  of 
Life  of  uncombined  resourceless  wage- earners — has  grave 
defects.  It  is,  in  the  first  place,  a  weak  bulwark,  seldom 
able  to  withstand  the  exceptional  pressure  of  times  of 
adversity,  especially  as  it  often  fails  to  cover  equally  the 
whole  length  of  the  line.  Moreover,  it  is  usually  weakest 
in  its  upper  parts,  so  that  the  employers,  in  periods  of  great 
pressure,  always  succeed  in  planing  it  down  a  little.  On 
the  other  hand,  owing  to  the  absence  of  any  deliberate 
concert,  it  cannot  practically  be  raised  by  the  workmen's 
own  efforts,  even  when  the  pressure  is  withdrawn,  and  thus, 
in  the  absence  of  any  better  protection  or  of  the  intervention 
of  some  outside  force,  it  is  apt  to  become  gradually  lower 
and  lower.  These  defects  arise,  as  we  shall  see,  from  (i) 
the  necessary  indefmiteness  of  a  merely  instinctive  Standard 
of  Life,  (2)  the  absence  of  any  material  support  for  the 
wage-earner's  stubbornness,  and  (3)  the  impossibility  with- 
out concerted  action  of  adjusting  the  workmen's  instinctive 
demands  so  as  to  meet  the  changing  circumstances  of  the 
industry. 

customary  minimum  Standard  of  Life,  but  who  have  no  maximum  ;  that  is  to 
say,  they  will  be  stimulated  to  intenser  effort  and  new  wants  by  every  increase  of 
income.  There  are  races  who,  like  the  African  negro,  have  no  assignable  mini- 
mum, but  a  very  low  maximum  ;  they  will  work,  that  is,  for  indefinitely  low 
wages,  but  cannot  be  induced  to  work  at  all  once  their  primitive  wants  are 
satisfied.  Finally,  there  is  the  Jew,  who,  as  we  think,  is  unique  in  possessing 
neither  a  minimum  nor  a  maximum  ;  he  will  accept  the  lowest  terms  rather  than 
remain  out  of  employment ;  as  he  rises  in  the  world  new  wants  stimulate  him  to 
increased  intensity  of  effort,  and  no  amount  of  income  causes  him  to  slacken  his 
indefatigable  activity.  To  this  remarkable  elasticity  in  the  Standard  of  Life  is, 
we  suggest,  to  be  attributed  both  the  wealth  and  the  poverty  of  the  Jews — the 
striking  fact  that  their  wage-earning  class  is  permanently  the  poorest  in  all  Europe, 
whilst  individual  Jews  are  the  wealthiest  men  of  their  respective  countries. 

The  position  of  the  English  working-woman  in  this  connection  would  especi- 
ally repay  inquiry.  The  poverty-stricken  widow,  with  children  depending  on 
her  for  bread,  will  accept  any  rate  of  wages  or  any  length  of  hours  rather  than 
refuse  employment.  On  the  other  hand,  the  well-brought-up  daughter  of  the 
artisan  will  obstinately  insist  on  certain  conditions  of  decency,  comfort,  and 
"respectability"  in  her  work.  But  owing  to  the  fact  that  she  so  often  is  not 
wholly  dependent  on  her  wages,  she  is  apt  to  accept  any  rate  of  pay  rather  than 
leave  a  comfortable  and  well-conducted  factory,  and  employers  often  complain 
that  no  stimulus  of  piecework  or  bonus  will  induce  such  women-workers  to  increase 
their  effort  beyond  a  somewhat  low  maximum. 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  699 

The  lack  of  definiteness  is  an  essential  feature  of  any 
merely  instinctive  standard.  What  the  isolated  individual 
workman  feels  is  that  he  is  entitled  to  a  certain  mode  of 
living,  a  certain  vague  quantum  of  weekly  expenditure,  in 
return  for  an  equally  vague  quantum  of  daily  work.  Each 
man  translates  this  for  himself  into  terms  of  wages,  hours, 
etc.,  and  the  translations  of  thousands  of  men  in  different 
parts  of  the  country  inevitably  differ  among  themselves. 
All  engineers,  for  instance,  would  agree  that  fifteen  shillings 
a  week  was  far  below  their  minimum  standard.  But,  in  the 
absence  of  any  concerted  action,  they  would  differ  among 
themselves  as  to  whether  its  money  equivalent  at  a  particular 
time  and  place  was  twenty-seven  or  twenty-nine  shillings  a 
week,  or  whether  any  given  piecework  rate  was  or  was  not 
a  fair  one.  Still  more  indefinite  is  the  workman's  instinctive 
Standard  of  Life  with  regard  to  the  length  of  the  working 
day,  meal  times,  and  holidays  ;  fines  and  deductions  of  every 
kind  ;  the  conditions  of  over  -  crowding  and  ventilation, 
decency  and  safety,  under  which  his  work  is  done  ;  and  the 
wear  and  tear  of  nerves,  muscles,  and  clothes  to  which  he  is 
exposed.  These  differences  of  translation  are  the  employer's 
opportunity.  By  constantly  insisting  upon  taking,  as  the 
standard  on  any  point,  the  lowest  translation  made  by  any 
candidate  for  employment,  he  is  able  gradually  to  beat  all 
the  others  down  to  that  level. 

It  is  a  no  less  serious  cause  of  weakness  that,  in  the 
absence  of  any  collective  reserve  fund,  the  isolated  individual 
worker  cannot  hope  to  be  able  to  stand  out  long  against  an 
obstinate  employer.  However  strong  may  be  the  repugnance 
to  accept  what  is  felt  to  be  less  than  the  standard  wage,  the 
workman  who  has  no  other  resources  than  the  sale  of  his 
labor  will  find  himself  every  day  more  strongly  tempted  by 
necessity  to  accept  something  less  than  he  claims.  When 
he  is  once  in  employment,  his  outspoken  revolt  against  any 
"  nibbling  "  at  wages,  "  cribbing  time,"  or  other  worsening  of 
the  conditions,  will  be  checked,  especially  in  periods  of  slack- 
ness, by  his  reluctance  to  "  quarrel  with  his  bread  and  butter." 


700  Trade  Union  Theory 

What  the  most  necessitous  man  submits  to,  all  the  others 
soon  find  themselves  pressed  to  put  up  with.  Thus,  in  the 
absence  of  any  financial  strengthening  of  the  weakest 
members,  the  bulwark  of  a  merely  instinctive  Standard  of 
Life  insidiously  gives  way  before  employers'  importunities. 

Finally,  whilst  the  bulwark  of  a  Standard  of  Life  is 
always  yielding  under  the  pressure  of  severe  competition,  it 
does  not  get  systematically  built  up  again  in  the  seasons 
when  the  pressure  is  lightened.  To  the  capitalist  the  scanty 
profits  of  lean  years  are  made  up  by  largely  swollen  gains 
in  the  alternating  periods  of  commercial  prosperity.  .  But  a 
wage  determined  only  by  an  instinctive  Standard  of  Life 
does  not  rise  merely  because  the  employers  are  temporarily 
making  larger  profits.  The  "  habits  and  customs "  of  a 
people — their  ideas  of  what  is  necessary  for  comfort  and 
social  decency — may,  in  the  slow  course  of  generations  of 
prosperity,  silently  and  imperceptibly  change  for  the  better, 
but  they  are  unaffected  by  the  swift  and  spasmodic  fluctua- 
tions which  characterise  modern  industry.  Thus,  in  years  of 
good  trade,  when  no  competent  man  need  remain  long 
unemployed,  though  the  pushing  workman  may,  without  a 
Trade  Union,  temporarily  exact  better  terms,  the  class  as  a 
whole  is  apt  to  get  only  regular  employment  at  its  accustomed 
livelihood.  In  the  absence  of  mutual  consultation  and 
concerted  action,  individuals  may  aspire  to  a  higher  standard, 
but  there  can  be  no  simultaneous  and  identical  rise,  and 
thus  no  new  consensus  of  feeling  is  brought  to  the  aid  of  the 
Individual  Bargaining  of  the  weaker  men. 

Trade  Unionism,  to  put  it  briefly,  remedies  all  these 
defects  of  a  merely  instinctive  Standard  of  Life.  By  inter- 
preting the  standard  into  precise  and  uniform  conditions 
of  employment  it  gives  every  member  of  the  combination 
a  definite  and  identical  minimum  to  stand  out  for,  and  an 
exact  measure  by  which  to  test  any  new  proposition  of  the 
employer.  The  reader  of  our  descriptions  of  the  elaborate 
standard  rates  and  piecework  lists,  the  scales  fixing  working 
hours  and  limiting  overtime,  and  the  special  rules  for  sanita- 


The  Higgling  of  the  Market  70 1 

tion  and  safety,  which  together  make  up  the  body  of  Trade 
Union  Regulations,  will  appreciate  with  what  fervor  and 
persistency  the  Trade  Unions  have  pursued  this  object  of 
giving  the  indispensable  definiteness  to  the  Standard  of  Life 
of  each  section  of  wage-earners.  And  when  we  pass  from 
the  Regulations  of  Trade  Unionism  to  its  characteristic 
Methods,  we  may  now  see  how  exactly  these  are  calculated 
to  remedy  the  other  shortcomings  of  the  wage -earners' 
instinctive  defence.  By  the  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance, 
the  most  necessitous  workman,  who  would  otherwise  be  the 
weakest  part  of  the  position,  is  freed  from  the  pressure  of 
his  special  necessities,  and  placed  in  as  good  a  position  as 
his  fellows  to  resist  the  employer's  encroachments.  The 
provision  of  a  common  fund  enables,  in  fact,  all  the  members 
alike  to  get  what  the  economists  have  called  a  "  reserve 
price"  on  their  labor.  Thus,  the  bulwark  is  made  equally 
strong  all  along  the  line.  But  the  Method  of  Mutual 
Insurance  also  carries  a  stage  further  this  strengthening  of 
the  weak  parts  of  the  defence.  The  money  saved  in  good 
years,  when  the  Out  of  Work  benefit  is  little  drawn  upon, 
will  be  used  to  support  the  members  in  times  of  slack  trade, 
when  the  pressure  will  be  greatest.  Thus,  the  bulwark  is 
specially  strengthened  against  the  advancing  tide.  The 
Method  of  Collective  Bargaining  brings  a  new  kind  of 
support.  When  the  terms  of  the  contract  are  settled,  not 
separately  by  the  individual  workmen  concerned,  but  jointly 
by  appointed  agents  on  their  behalf,  an  additional  barrier  is 
interposed  between  the  pressure  acting  through  the  employer, 
and  the  apprehensions  and  ignorances  of  his  wage-earners. 
The  conclusion  of  collective  agreements  not  only  excludes, 
as  we  have  explained,  the  influence  of  the  exigencies  of 
particular  workmen,  particular  firms,  or  particular  districts, 
but  it  also  gives  the  combined  manual  workers  the  invaluable 
assistance  of  a  professional  expert  who,  in  knowledge  of  the 
trade  and  trained  capacity  for  bargaining,  may  even  be 
superior  to  the  employer  himself.  The  Method  of  Collective 
Bargaining  has  the  further  advantage  over  reliance  on  a 


Trade  Union  Theory 

merely  instinctive  Standard  of  Life  that  the  terms  can  be 
quickly  raised  so  as  to  take  advantage  of  any  time  of  rising 
profits,  and  indefinitely  adjusted  so  as  to  meet  the  require- 
ments of  an  ever-changing  industry.  Finally,  the  Method 
of  Legal  Enactment — the  use  of  which  by  the  workmen 
demands  a  high  degree  of  voluntary  organisation,  and  above 
all,  an  expert  professional  staff  of  salaried  officers — 
absolutely  secures  one  element  of  the  Standard  of  Life  after 
another  by  embodying  them  in  our  factory  code,  and  thus 
fortifies  the  workmen's  original  bulwark  by  the  unyielding 
buttress  of  the  law  of  the  land. 

But  this  general  description  of  Trade  Unionism  as  the 
Dyke  of  a  definite  Standard  of  Life,  strengthened  by  the 
existence  of  a  common  purse,  the  services  of  expert 
negotiators,  and  the  protection  of  the  magistrate — though 
it  serves  to  indicate  its  place  in  the  higgling  of  the  market 
— affords  too  indefinite  a  mark  for  useful  economic  criticism. 
In  the  Second  Part  of  this  work  we  laid  before  the  reader 
an  exhaustive  analysis  of  the  Regulations  imposed  by  British 
Trade  Unionists,  of  the  Methods  by  which  they  seek  their 
ends,  and,  finally,  of  the  far-reaching  views  of  social  ex- 
pediency upon  which  the  policy  of  the  various  sections  of 
the  Trade  Union  world  is  determined.  In  this  analysis  we 
distinguished  between  what  is  universal  and  what  is  only 
partial,  and,  above  all,  between  the  elements  that  are  deepening 
and  extending,  and  those  that  are  dwindling  in  scope  and 
intensity.  What  we  have  now  to  do  is  to  follow  out  the 
economic  effects  of  each  type,  and  thus  enable  the  reader  to 
form  some  general  estimate  of  the  results  upon  our  industrial 
development,  of  the  actual  content  of  contemporary  Trade 
Unionism  in  this  country. 


CHAPTER    III 

THE    ECONOMIC    CHARACTERISTICS    OF    TRADE    UNIONISM 

THE  economist  and  the  statesman  will  judge  Trade  Unionism, 
not  by  its  results  in  improving  the  position  of  a  particular 
section  of  workmen  at  a  particular  time,  but  by  its  effects 
on  the  permanent  efficiency  of  the  nation.  If  any  of  the 
Methods  and  Regulations  of  Trade  Unionism  result  in  the 
choice  of  less  efficient  factors  of  production  than  would  other- 
wise have  been  used  ;  if  they  compel  the  adoption  of  a  lower 
type  of  organisation  than  would  have  prevailed  without  them  ; 
and  especially  if  they  tend  to  lessen  the  capacity  or  degrade 
the  character  of  either  manual  laborers  or  brain -workers,  that 
part  of  Trade  Unionism,  however  advantageous  it  may  seem 
to  particular  sections  of  workmen,  will  stand  condemned.  If, 
on  the  other  hand,  any  Trade  Union  Methods  and  Regulations 
are  found  to  promote  the  selection  of  the  most  efficient  factors 
of  production,  whether  capital,  brains,  or  labor  ;  if  they  tend 
to  a  better  organisation  of  these  factors,  and  above  all,  if 
their  effect  is  progressively  to  increase  the  activities  and 
improve  the  character  of  both  brain  and  manual  workers, 
then,  in  spite  of  any  apparent  contraction  of  the  personal 
power  of  the  capitalist  class,  they  will  be  approved  by  the 
economist  as  tending  to  heighten  the  faculties  and  enlarge 
the  enjoyments  of  the  community  as  a  whole.1 

1  Here  and  throughout  this  chapter  we  proceed  on  the  assumption  that  it  is 
desirable  for  the  community  to  "progress";  that  is  to  say,  that  its  members 
should  attain,  generation  after  generation,  a  wider  and  fuller  life  by  developing 


704  Trade  Union  Theory 

Let  us  take  first  the  Trade  Union  Regulations,  for,  if 
these  have  an  injurious  effect,  it  is  unnecessary  to  consider 
by  what  methods  they  are  enforced.  Notwithstanding  their 
almost  infinite  variety  of  technical  detail  these  Regulations 
can,  as  we  have  seen,  be  reduced  to  two  economic 
devices :  Restriction  of  Numbers  and  the  Common  Rule. 
To  the  former  type  belong  the  ancient  Trade  Union 
prescriptions  as  to  Apprenticeship,  the  exclusion  of  new 
competitors  from  a  trade,  and  the  assertion  of  a  vested 
interest  in  a  particular  occupation.  The  latter  type  includes 
the  more  modern  rules  directly  fixing  a  Standard  Rate, 
a  Normal  Day,  and  definite  conditions  of  Sanitation 
and  Safety. 


(a]  The  Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers 

There  is  a  certain  sense  in  which  every  regulation, 
whether  imposed  by  law  or  public  custom,  laid  down  by 
the  employer  or  insisted  on  by  the  Trade  Union,  may  be 
said  to  restrict  the  entrance  to  an  occupation.  It  is  inherent 
in  any  rule  that  its  enforcement  incidentally  excludes  those 
who,  for  one  reason  or  another,  cannot  or  will  not  conform 
to  it.  Thus,  a  firm  which,  as  a  matter  of  business  routine, 
requires  its  employees  to  be  regular  in  their  attendance,  or 
to  abstain  from  smoking  or  drinking  at  their  work,  or  which 

increased  faculties  and  satisfying  more  complicated  desires.  When,  therefore, 
for  the  sake  of  shortness,  we  use  the  phrase  "Selection  of  the  Fittest,"  we  mean 
the  fittest  to  achieve  this  object  of  social  evolution;  and  by  the  phrase  "Func- 
tional Adaptation,"  we  mean  the  adaptation  of  the  individual  to  an  increase  in 
the  strength  and  complexity  of  his  faculties  and  desires,  as  distinguished  from 
"  Degeneration,"  the  corresponding  decrease  in  faculties  and  desires.  We  are 
aware  that  this  assumption  would  not  command  universal  assent.  The  whole 
Eastern  world,  for  instance,  proclaims  the  opposite  philosophy  of  life  ;  an  Eng- 
lishman, it  is  said,  "seeks  happiness  in  the  multiplication  of  his  possessions,  a 
Hindoo  in  the  diminution  of  his  wants."  And  there  are,  if  we  mistake  not, 
many  persons  in  the  Western  world  whose  dislike  of  modern  progress  springs, 
half  unconsciously,  from  an  objection  to  a  life  which,  whilst  satisfying  more 
complicated  desires,  makes  increasing  demands  upon  the  faculties.  To  such 
persons  the  whole  argument  contained  in  this  chapter  will  be  an  additional  reason 
for  disliking  the  more  modern  manifestations  of  Trade  Unionism. 


Economic  Characteristics  705 

systematically  dismisses  those  who  fail  to  attain  a  certain 
speed,  or  repeatedly  make  mistakes,  thereby  restricts  its 
employment  to  operatives  of  a  certain  standard  of  conduct 
or  capacity.  Similarly,  the  universal  Trade  Union  insistence 
on  a  Standard  Rate  of  payment  for  a  given  quota  of  work 
excludes,  from  the  particular  occupation  those  whom  no 
employer  will  engage  at  that  rate.  And  when  any 
regulation,  either  of  the  employers  or  of  the  workmen,  is 
embodied  in  the  law  of  the  land,  this  new  Factory  Act 
automatically  closes  the  occupation  to  which  it  applies  to 
all  persons  who  cannot  or  will  not  conform  to  its  prescriptions. 
The  kingdom  itself  may  be  closed  to  certain  races  by -a 
Sanitary  Code,  with  which  their  religion  forbids  them  to 
comply.  But  there  is  a  great  distinction  in  character  and 
results  between  the  incidentally  restrictive  effects  of  a 
Common  Rule,  to  which  every  one  is  free  to  conform,  and 
the  direct  exclusion  of  specified  classes  of  persons,  whether 
they  conform  or  not,  by  regulations  totally  prohibiting  their 
entrance.  In  the  present  section  we  deal  solely  with  direct 
attempts  to  secure  or  maintain  a  more  or  less  complete 
"  monopoly  "  of  particular  occupations,  either  by  limiting  the 
number  of  learners,  or  by  excluding,  on  grounds  of  sex, 
previous  occupation,  or  lack  of  apprenticeship,  persons  whom 
an  employer  is  willing  to  engage,  and  who  are  themselves 
willing  to  work,  in  strict  conformity  with  the  standard  con- 
ditions of  the  trade. 

From  the  standpoint  of  industrial  efficiency,  the  most 
obvious  characteristic  of  the  Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers 
is  the  manner  in  which  it  influences  the  selection  of  the 
factors  of  production.  When  situations  are  filled  by  com- 
petitive examination,  as  for  instance  in  the  English  Civil 
Service,  it  is  recognised  that  any  restriction  on  the  number 
of  candidates — still  more,  any  limitation  of  the  candidates  to 
persons  of  particular  families,  particular  classes,  or  particular 
antecedents  —  lowers  the  average  of  quality  among  the 
successful  competitors.  The  same  consequence  results  from 
any  restriction  which  prevents  an  employer  from  filling  all 
VOL.  II  2  Z 


706  Trade  Union  Theory 

his  vacancies  as  they  occur  by  selecting  the  most  efficient 
operatives,  wherever  he  can  find  them.  The  mere  fixing  of 
a  ratio  of  apprentices  to  journeymen  will  exclude  from  the 
trade  some  boys  who  would  otherwise  have  learnt  it,  and 
who  might  have  proved  the  most  capable  operatives  at  the 
craft.  This  is  certain  to  be  the  case  if  the  regulation  takes 
the  form  of  exacting  a  high  entrance  fee,  or  of  confining 
admission  to  craftsmen's  sons.  Even  without  any  restrictions 
on  apprenticeship,  the  requirement  that  the  trade  must  be 
entered  before  a  prescribed  age,  by  excluding  the  quick- 
witted outsider  who  desires  to  change  his  occupation  in  after 
years,  necessarily  tends  to  limit  the  range  of  the  employer's 
choice,  and  hence  to  make  the  average  level  of  capacity  lower 
in  the  protected  trade  than  it  would  otherwise  be.  And 
whilst  this  limitation  on  the  process  of  selection  is  injurious 
even  in  old-established  trades,  it  becomes  plainly  more  harm- 
ful when  the  question  is  the  choice  of  men  to  work  a  new 
machine  or  perform  some  novel  service.  The  more  restricted 
the  field  from  which  the  capitalist  can  pick  these  new  opera- 
tives, the  lower  will  be  their  average  level  of  capacity.  Nor 
is  it  merely  the  absence  of  unemployed  workmen  that  im- 
pedes the  employer's  freedom  to  select  the  most  efficient  man 
to  fill  his  vacancy.  The  constant  existence  of  a  remnant  of 
unemployed  may  enable  an  employer  to  get  a  "  cheap  hand," 
or  help  him  to  lower  wages  all  round  ;  but  the  competition 
of  this  "  reserve  army "  does  little  or  nothing  to  promote 
efficiency.  The  fact  that  a  man  is  out  of  work  affords  a 
presumption  that  he  has,  for  the  moment,  greater  needs,  but 
not  that  he  has  greater  faculties.  To  compel  employers  to 
fill  all  vacancies  from  the  unemployed  remnant  of  the  trade, 
in  preference  to  promoting  the  ablest  members  of  the  next 
lower  grade,  is  often  to  force  them  to  engage,  not  the  work- 
men who  promise  to  be  the  most  efficient,  but  those  who 
have  proved  themselves  below  the  average  in  regularity  or 
capacity.  On  the  other  hand,  if  the  Restriction  of  Numbers 
is  carried  so  far  that  only  one  candidate  presents  him- 
self to  fill  each  vacancy,  all  selection  disappears.  Had  the 


Economic  Characteristics  707 

regulations  of  the  Flint  Glass  Makers  and  the  Silk  Hatters 
been  enforced  with  absolute  universality  every  employer  in 
those  trades  would  have  found  himself  compelled,  whenever 
a  vacancy  occurred  in  his  establishment,  either  to  accept  the 
Trade  Union  nominee,  whatever  his  character  or  capacity,  or 
else  leave  the  situation  unfilled. 

And  whilst  any  limitation  of  the  persons  from  whom 
vacancies  can  be  filled  insidiously  lowers  the  quality  of  the 
recruits,  the  same  influence  deteriorates  the  men  already  in 
the  trade.  When  it  is  known  that  the  master  has  no  chance 
of  getting  better  workmen,  or  that  his  choice  will  be  limited 
to  the  unemployed  remnant  of  the  trade,  the  "  average 
sensual  man "  is  apt  to  lose  much  of  his  incentive  to 
efficiency,  and  even  to  regularity  of  conduct.  In  those 
trades  in  which  the  Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers  is 
effectually  practised,  an  employer  habitually  puts  up  with  a 
higher  degree  of  irregularity,  carelessness,  and  inefficiency  in 
his  existing  staff,  than  he  would  if  he  could  freely  promote  a 
learner  or  an  assistant  to  the  better-paid  situation. 

What  is  not  so  generally  recognised  is  that,  in  trades  in 
which  the  workmen  are  able  to  make  effective  use  of  the 
Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers,  the  brain-workers  of  the 
trade  are  themselves  less  select,  and  suffer  a  similar  loss  of 
incentive  to  efficiency.  In  such  completely  organised  and  old- 
fashioned  trades  as  glass-blowing  and  hand  papermaking,  the 
policy  of  limiting  the  numbers  has  been  so  effectively  carried 
out  that  capitalists  who,  when  trade  is  brisk  and  profits  large, 
might  desire  to  set  up  new  works  in  competition  with  the 
old  establishments,  are  actually  stopped  by  the  difficulty  of 
obtaining  an  adequate  supply  of  skilled  workmen.  Hence, 
old-fashioned  family  concerns,  with  sleepy  management  and 
obsolete  plant,  find  the  Trade  Union  regulations  a  positive 
protection  against  competition.  This  is  frequently  admitted 
in  the  negotiations  between  masters  and  men.  In  1874,  for 
instance,  the  spokesman  of  the  hand  papermakers  put 
forward  this  profitable  effect  of  his  union's  restrictive  regula- 
tions as  a  reason  why  the  employers  should  concede  better 


708  Trade  Union  Theory 

terms.  "  If,"  said  he,  "  the  men  have  good  wages,  the 
masters  as  a  rule  make  large  profits,  and  large  profits  are 
inducements  which  cause  fresh  capital  to  be  embarked  in  a 
trade.  If,  however,  the  men  have  a  limit  to  the  supply  of 
labor,  no  matter  what  the  profits  are,  fresh  capital  cannot  be 
introduced,  because  if  a  man  starts  fresh  vats  he  will  have 
no  workmen  to  go  on  with.  The  rule  as  to  limiting  the 
supply  of  labor  therefore  works  both  ways.  As  far  as  our 
position  in  the  vat  trade  is  concerned  we  are  like  a  close 
corporation.  ...  It  would  be  a  great  inducement  for  capital 
to  enter  the  trade  if  labor  could  be  got,  but  .  .  .  according 
to  our  Rules  and  Regulations,  competition  is  checked." l 

From  the  point  of  view  of  the  consumer,  this  use  of  the 
Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers  by  the  workmen,  and  their 
formation  of  a  close  corporation  seems,  at  first  sight,  analogous 
to  the  establishment  of  a  capitalist  ring  or  trust.  Both 
expedients  aim  at  creating  a  profitable  monopoly,  for  the 
benefit  of  those  already  in  the  trade,  by  the  exclusion  of  new 
competitors.  But  there  is  an  important  difference  between 
the  workmen's  monopoly  and  that  of  the  capitalists,  in  the 

1  Arbitration  on  the  Question  of  an  Advance  in  Wages.  .  .  .  Rupert  Kettle, 
Q.C.,  Arbitrator  (Maidstone,  p.  64,  1874). 

Similar  conditions  seem  to  have  prevailed  in  the  early  factory  industries 
of  France,  after  the  impulse  given  by  Henry  II.  (ca.  1550).  Towards  the  end 
of  the  seventeenth  century  the  workers  in  the  paper-mills,  carpet  factories,  and 
manufactories  of  looking-glasses  are  described  as  forming  strong  though  un- 
authorised corporations,  which  were  encouraged  by  the  employers,  and  which 
were  recruited  exclusively  from  sons  and  sons-in-law  of  the  workmen,  so  as 
to  form  virtually  a  hereditary  monopoly.  The  papermakers  were  so  powerful 
as  to  lead  to  special  repressive  laws  for  this  industry  in  1793  and  again  in 
1796. — Du  Cellier,  Hisloire  des  Classes  Laborieuses  en  France  (Paris,  1860), 
pp.  259,  260,  334  ;  and,  as  regards  the  papermakers,  the  articles  by  C.  M.  Briquet 
in  the  Revue  Internationale  de  Sociologie,  March  1897. 

It  is  in  this  exclusion  of  new  capital,  and  the  consequent  check  to  the  process 
of  Selection  of  the  Fittest  among  the  employers,  that  we  discover  the  fundamental 
objection  to  the  policy  of  Restriction  of  Output,  which  we  described  in  our 
chapter  on  "  Continuity  of  Employment."  It  is,  as  we  explained,  impossible  for 
the  Trade  Union,  by  any  methods  or  regulations  of  its  own,  to  limit  the  aggregate 
output.  But  the  employers  may,  and  occasionally  do  effect  such  a  limitation, 
with  or  without  the  co-operation  of  the  Trade  Union  concerned.  In  so  far  as 
this  is  effected  by  preventing  or  discouraging  new  capitalist  enterprise,  it  tends  to 
diminish  the  efficiency  of  the  industry,  by  checking  the  "  elimination  of  the  unfit  " 
among  the  employers. 


Economic  Characteristcs  7°9 

type  of  industrial  organisation  that  they  set  up,  and  in  their 
results  upon  productive  efficiency.  A  successful  Trust  loses, 
it  is  true,  the  goad  to  improvement  that  comes  from  the  free 
fight  with  other  competitors.  On  the  other  hand,  it  retains 
undiminished,  and  gives  full  scope  to  the  profit -maker's 
normal  incentive  to  go  on  increasing  his  business  and  his 
income.  So  long  as  an  additional  increment  of  capital 
promises  to  yield  more  than  the  rate  paid  to  the  banker  or 
debenture  holder  for  its  use,  the  capitalist  Trust  will  strive  to 
enlarge  its  output,  and  make  the  utmost  possible  improvement 
in  its  processes.  The  owners  of  even  the  most  absolute 
monopoly  do  not  find  it  pay  to  raise  the  price  of  their 
product  in  such  a  way  as  to  cause  any  serious  falling-off  in 
the  sales  ;  more  commonly,  indeed,  as  in  the  case  of  the 
Standard  Oil  Company,1  they  get  an  advantage  by  actually 
lowering  the  price  in  order  to  stimulate  the  demand.  They 
are,  in  any  case,  perpetually  tempted  to  engage  the  ablest 
brains  in  the  Trust's  service,  as  well  as  to  use  the  best  machines 
and  the  latest  inventions  ;  for  every  cheapening  of  production 
that  can  be  effected  enures  wholly  to  their  own  advantage. 
Hence,  however  large  and  disproportionate  may  be  the 
income  drawn  by  the  owners  of  the  Trust,  however  arbitrary 
and  oppressive  may  be  the  social  power  that  it  exercises, 
this  capitalist  monopoly  has  at  any  rate  the  economic 
advantage  of  selecting  and  organising  the  factors  of  pro- 
duction in  such  a  way  as  to  turn  out  its  product  at  an  ever 
diminishing  cost.  A  close  corporation  of  workmen  has, 
on  the  contrary,  no  interest  in  enlarging  its  business.  The 
individual  operatives  who  enjoy  the  monopoly  have  only  their 
own  energy  to  sell,  and  they  are  accordingly  interested  in 
getting  in  return  for  their  definitely  limited  output  as  high 
a  price  as  possible.  If  they  can,  by  raising  price,  exact  the 
same  income  for  a  smaller  number  of  hours'  work,  it  will 
positively  pay  them  to  leave  some  of  the  world's  demand 
unsatisfied.  They  have  nothing  to  gain  by  cheapening  the 

1  See  Wealth  Against  Commonwealth,  by  Henry  D.  Lloyd  (London,  1894) ; 
E.  von  Halle,  Trusts. 


7io  Trade  Union  Theory 

process  of  production,  and  they  stand  actually  to  lose  by 
every  invention  or  improvement  in  organisation  that  enables 
their  product  to  be  turned  out  with  less  labor.  Any  altera- 
tion, in  short,  will  be  repugnant  to  them,  as  involving  a 
change  of  habit,  new  exertion,  and  no  pecuniary  gain. 
Rather  than  forego  the  utmost  possible  individual  wage,  it 
would  even  pay  them  to  stop  all  recruiting,  and  progressively 
raise  their  price  as  their  members  drop  off  one  by  one,  until 
the  whole  industry  dwindled  away. 

So  far  the  Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers  appears 
wholly  injurious  to  industrial  efficiency.  There  is,  however, 
one  important  effect  in  another  direction.  If,  in  the  absence 
of  all  regulation,  the  employers  are  free  without  let  or  hind- 
rance to  make  the  best  bargain  they  can  with  the  individual 
wage-earners,  whole  sections  of  the  population,  men,  women, 
and  children,  will  be  compelled  to  live  and  toil  under  con- 
ditions seriously  injurious  to  their  health  and  industrial 
efficiency.  Nor  is  this  merely  an  empirical  inference  from 
the  history  of  an  unregulated  factory  system,  and  from  the 
contemporary  facts  of  the  sweated  industries.  It  is  now 
theoretically  demonstrated,  as  we  saw  in  our  chapter  on 
"The  Verdict  of  the  Economists,"  that  under  "perfect 
competition,"  and  complete  mobility  between  one  occupation 
and  another,  the  common  level  of  wages  tends  to  be  no 
more  than  "  the  net  produce  due  to  the  additional  labor  of 
the  marginal  laborer,"  who  is  on  the  verge  of  not  being 
employed  at  all !  The  Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers 
manifestly  enables  the  privileged  insiders  to  make  a  better 
bargain  with  their  employers — that  is  to  say,  to  insist  on 
better  sanitary  conditions,  shorter  and  more  regular  hours, 
and,  above  all,  a  wage  which  provides  for  their  families  as 
well  as  themselves,  a  more  adequate  supply  of  food  and 
clothing.  However  equivocal  may  be  the  device  by  which 
this  higher  Standard  of  Life  is  secured,  there  can  be  no  doubt 
that,  in  itself,  it  renders  possible  a  far  higher  degree  of  skill, 
conduct,  and  general  efficiency  than  the  long  hours,  unhealthy 
conditions,  and  bare  subsistence  wages  which  are  found 


Economic  Characteristics  7 1 1 

prevailing  in  the  unregulated  trades.  In  such  a  case  the 
Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers  must  be  credited  with 
indirectly  preventing  evil,  and  with  producing  a  certain 
increase  of  efficiency,  as  a  set-off  against  the  direct  weaken- 
ing of  the  incentive  to  improvement  that  we  have  been 
describing.  Thus,  it  is  easy  to  accuse  the  Glass  Bottle 
Makers  of  injuring  their  industry  by  their  drastic  Restriction 
of  Numbers.  But  it  is  open  to  them  to  reply  that  the  very 
existence  of  their  high  level  of  technical  skill  depends  on 
their  maintaining  a  high  Standard  of  Life  ;  that  the  Restric- 
tion of  Numbers  has  been  an  effective  means  of  maintaining 
this  high  standard ;  and  that  without  it,  their  combination 
would  have  crumbled  away,  their  lists  of  Piecework  Rates 
would  have  been  destroyed  by  Individual  Bargaining,  and 
they  themselves  would  have  sunk  to  the  low  level  of  the 
present  outcasts  of  the  trade,  those  incompetent  and  un- 
organised workmen  who  pick  up  starvation  wages  by 
making,  in  cellars  and  "  crib-shops,"  the  commonest  kind  of 
medicine  bottles.  It  was  this  consideration  that  induced 
J.  S.  Mill  to  declare  that  such  a  "  partial  rise  of  wages,  if 
not  gained  at  the  expense  of  the  remainder  of  the  working 
class,  ought  not  to  be  regarded  as  an  evil.  The  consumer 
indeed,  must  pay  for  it,  but  cheapness  of  goods  is  desirable 
only  when  the  cause  of  it  is  that  their  production  costs 
little  labor,  and  not  when  occasioned  by  that  labor  being  ill- 
remunerated.  If,  therefore,  no  improvement  were  to  be 
hoped  for  in  the  general  circumstances  of  the  working 
classes  the  success  of  a  portion  of  them,  however  small,  in 
keeping  their  wages  by  combination  above  the  market  rate 
would  be  wholly  a  matter  of  satisfaction."1  Hence,  from 
the  point  of  view  of  those  who  regarded  Restriction  of 
Numbers  as  the  only  means  by  which  wages  could  be 
maintained  at  anything  above  subsistence  level,  there  was 
no  argument  against  a  Trade  Union  which  adopted  this 
expedient  to  save  its  members  from  slipping  into  the 
universal  morass.  During  the  fifty  years  that  followed 

1  J.  S.  Mill,  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  Book  V.  ch.  x.  §  5,  p.  564. 


712  Trade  Union  Theory 

the  repeal  of  the  Combination  Laws  the  Trade  Unionists 
were  incessantly  told  that  "  combinations  of  workmen  .  .  . 
always  fail  to  uphold  wages  at  an  artificial  rate,  unless  they 
also  limit  the  number  of  competitors." ]  When  the  Flint 
Glass  Makers  and  the  Compositors,  the  Papermakers  and 
Engineers  adopted  stringent  apprenticeship  regulations  as 
one  of  the  principal  devices  of  their  Trade  Unionism,  in  so  far 
as  they  were  taking  the  only  recognised  means  of  protecting 
from  a  useless  degradation  their  relatively  high  Standard  of 
Life,  and  of  maintaining  unimpaired  their  relatively  high 
level  of  industrial  efficiency,  they  were  but  applying  the 
current  teachings  of  Political  Economy. 

To  sum  up,  the  Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers,  by 
constantly  baulking  the  free  selection  of  the  most  capable 
manual  workers  and  entrepreneurs ;  by  removing  from  both 
classes  the  incentive  due  to  the  fear  of  supersession  ;  by 
stereotyping  processes  and  restricting  output ;  and  by  per- 
sistently hindering  the  re-organisation  of  industry  on  the 
most  improved  basis,  lowers  the  level  of  productive  efficiency 
all  round.  On  the  other  hand,  as  compared  with  "  perfect 
competition,"  it  has  the  economic  advantage  of  fencing-off 
particular  families,  grades,  or  classes  from  the  general  degrada- 
tion, and  thus  preserving  to  the  community,  in  these  privi- 
leged groups,  a  store  of  industrial  traditions,  a  high  level  of 
specialised  skill,  and  a  degree  of  physical  health  and  general 
intelligence  unattainable  at  a  bare  subsistence  wage.  If, 
therefore,  we  had  to  choose  between  perfect  "  freedom  of 
competition,"  and  an  effective  but  moderate  use  of  the 
Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers  —  between,  for  in- 
stance, the  unregulated  factory  labor  of  the  Lancashire  of 
the  beginning  of  this  century,  on  the  one  hand,  and  the 
mediaeval  craft  gild  on  the  other — the  modern  economist 
would  hesitate  long  before  counselling  a  complete  abandon- 
ment of  the  old  device. 

1  J.  S.  Mill,  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  Book  II.  chap.  xiv.  §  6,  p.  243 
of  1865  edition  ;  see  also  p.  229,  "  Every  successful  combination  to  keep  up  wages 
owes  its  success  to  contrivances  for  restricting  the  number  of  the  competitors. " 


Economic  Characteristics  713 

We  are  fortunately  saved  from  so  embarrassing  a  choice. 
In  the  first  place,  an  effective  use  of  the  Device  of  Restriction 
of  Numbers  is  no  longer  practicable.  In  our  chapters  on 
"  The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  "  and  "  The  Right  to  a  Trade  " 
we  have  seen  how  small  and  dwindling  is  the  minority  of 
Trade  Unions  which  still  rely  on  this  means  of  protecting 
their  Standard  of  Life.  The  ever-growing  mobility  of 
capital,  and  the  incessant  revolutionising  of  industrial  pro- 
cesses render  impracticable,  in  the  vast  majority  of  occupa- 
tions, any  restriction,  by  the  Methods  of  Mutual  Insurance 
or  Collective  Bargaining,  of  the  candidates  for  employment. 
The  steadily-increasing  dislike  to  the  Doctrine  of  Vested 
Interests  makes  it  every  day  more  hopeless  to  set  up  or 
maintain,  by  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment,  any  limitation 
on  the  freedom  of  the  competent  individual  to  do  any  work 
for  which  he  is  positively  better  fitted,  than  those  by  whom 
it  has  hitherto  been  performed.  Thus,  only  an  infinitesimal 
number  of  Trade  Unions  actually  succeed  in  limiting 
the  number  of  persons  who  become  candidates  for 
employment  at  their  occupation.  It  is  true  that  large 
sections  of  the  Trade  Union  world  still,  as  we  have  seen, 
cling  to  the  old  device.  The  Compositors,  the  Engineers, 
the  Ironfounders,  the  factory  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives, 
and,  in  many  districts,  one  or  other  section  of  the 
building  trades  limit,  with  more  or  less  stringency,  the 
number  of  boy -learners  in  any  one  establishment.  This 
regulation  can,  however,  only  be  enforced  in  establishments 
or  districts  over  which  the  Trade  Union  has  exceptional  con- 
trol, and  it  is  entirely  nugatory  in  establishments  dispensing 
with  Trade  Union  labor,  and  in  districts  where  the  skilled 
workmen  are  only  partially  organised.  Hence,  as  we  have 
pointed  out  in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Entrance  to  a  Trade," 
these  Trade  Unions  are  not,  by  their  apprenticeship  regula- 
tions, limiting  the  number  of  candidates  for  employment ; 
they  are  merely  providing,  at  considerable  cost  to  themselves, 
that  the  boys  should  be  trained  in  the  least  skilled  department 
of  the  trade  ;  initiated  into  their  industrial  career  by  the 


714  Trade  Union  Theory 

worst  employers  and  the  most  indifferent  workmen  ;  and,  we 
may  add,  brought  up  with  the  feelings  and  traditions  of 
"  blacklegs,"  instead  of  those  of  good  Trade  Unionists. 
Whatever  advantages  may  be  thought  to  accrue  from  a 
systematic  and  successful  Restriction  of  Numbers,  the  partial 
and  lopsided  application  of  this  device  by  modern  Trade 
Unions  is,  we  believe,  economically  as  prejudicial  to  the 
strategic  position  of  their  own  members  as  it  is  to  the 
interests  of  the  rest  of  the  community. 

More  effectual  in  inducing  the  great  majority  of  Trade 
Unions  to  change  their  tactics  has  been  the  discovery — in 
flat  contradiction  to  J.  S.  Mill's  authoritative  dictum — that 
they  can  successfully  maintain  a  high  Standard  of  Life,  by  re- 
lying exclusively  on  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule.  Thus, 
the  Amalgamated  Association  of  Operative  Cotton-spinners 
or  the  Northumberland  Miners'  Mutual  Confident  Association 
— combinations  which  have,  for  a  whole  generation,  success- 
fully maintained  relatively  good  wages  and  short  hours, 
together  with  a  high  level  of  sanitation  and  safety — have 
never  interfered  in  the  employer's  free  choice  of  men,  what- 
ever their  antecedents,  to  fill  vacancies  in  their  respective 
trades.  In  the  case  of  the  Cotton-spinners  the  Trade  Union 
even  insists,  as  we  have  seen,  on  there  being  always  ten 
times  as  many  learners  as  would  suffice  to  keep  up  the 
trade.  In  so  far  as  the  Common  Rules  governing  these 
industries  are  enforced  by  law  this  may  easily  be  understood. 
The  Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers  in  no  way  increases 
the  power  of  a  Trade  Union  to  obtain  an  Act  of  Parliament 
or  to  press  for  the  rigid  application  of  existing  statutes  ;  it 
tends,  on  the  contrary,  to  diminish  this  power.  Any  success- 
ful limitation  of  numbers  necessarily  restricts  the  growth  of 
the  industry  in  question,  and  thus  lessens  the  electoral  area 
over  which  it  is  dominant,  whilst  the  maintenance  of  a  close 
monopoly  alienates  the  sympathy  of  the  excluded.  More 
paradoxical  is  the  fact  that  it  is  not,  in  practice,  found  to 
militate  against  the  maintenance  of  Common  Rules  by  Collec- 
tive Bargaining,  that  a  large  qumber  of  people  would  like  to 


Economic  Characteristics  715 

come  into  the  trade,  or  even  that  a  crowd  of  candidates 
apply  for  every  situation  that  is  vacant.  The  explanation 
of  this  paradox  must  be  sought  in  the  economic  characteristics 
of  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule. 


(U)   The  Device  of  the  Common  Rule 

We  have  sufficiently  explained,  in  our  chapters  on 
"  The  Standard  Rate,"  "  The  Normal  Day,"  and  "  Sanitation 
and  Safety,"  that  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule  is,  from  the 
workman's  point  of  view,  always  the  enforcement  of  a  mini- 
mum, below  which  no  employer  may  descend,  never  a  maxi- 
mum, beyond  which  he  may  not,  if  he  chooses,  offer  better 
terms.  This  is  specially  noticeable  where  the  Common  Rule 
is  enforced  by  law.  An  employer  who,  for  one  reason  or 
another,  desires  to  fill  his  works  with  the  most  respectable 
young  women,  does  not  restrict  himself  to  the  already  high 
standard  of  comfort  and  decency  enforced  by  the  Factory 
Act ;  he  sees  to  it  that  the  workrooms  are  cheerful,  warm, 
and  light ;  provides  dining-rooms  and  cloak-rooms,  hot  water, 
soap,  and  towels,  free  from  the  usual  irritating  charges  ;  takes 
care  to  prevent  any  opportunity  for  the  foreman's  petty 
tyrannies  ;  and  strives  to  make  a  spirit  of  kindly  considera- 
tion pervade  the  whole  establishment.  When  the  Trade 
Union  has  to  enforce  the  Common  Rule  by  Mutual  Insurance 
or  Collective  Bargaining,  it  never  objects  to  an  employer 
attracting  superior  workmen  to  his  establishment  by  adopt- 
ing a  scale  of  wages  in  excess  of  the  Standard  ;  by  intro- 
ducing an  Eight  Hours'  Day  ;  or  by  promising  to  pay  full 
wages  during  holidays  or  breakdowns.  The  mere  adoption 
of  a  Common  Rule,  even  if  it  does  no  more  than  give 
definiteness  and  uniformity  to  what  has  hitherto  been  the 
average,  current,  or  "  fair "  conditions  of  the  industry,  has 
therefore  the  psychological  effect  of  transforming  a  "  mean  " 
into  a  "  minimum  "  ;  and  hence  of  silently  setting  up,  in  the 


716  Trade  Union  Theory 

eyes  of  both  employers  and  workmen,  a  new  "  mean " 
between  the  best  and  worst  conditions  prevailing  in  the 
trade.1 

The  Device  of  the  Common  Rule  stands  in  sharpest 
contrast,  in  all  that  concerns  the  selection  of  the  factors  of 
production,  with  the  Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers.  The 
enforcement  in  any  industry  of  a  Standard  Rate,  a  Normal 
Day,  and  prescribed  conditions  of  Sanitation  and  Safety  does 
not  prevent  the  employer's  choice  of  one  man  rather  than 
another,  or  forbid  him  to  pick  out  of  the  crowd  of  applicants 
the  strongest,  most  skilful,  or  best -conducted  workman. 
Hence,  the  Common  Rule  in  no  way  abolishes  competition 
for  employment.  It  does  not  even  limit  the  intensity  of  such 
competition,  or  the  freedom  of  the  employer  to  take  advantage 
of  it.  All  that  it  does  is  to  transfer  the  pressure  from  one 
element  in  the  bargain  to  the  other — from  the  wage  to  the  work, 
from  price  to  quality.  In  fact,  this  exclusion,  from  influence 
on  the  contract,  of  all  degradation  of  price,  whether  it  takes 
the  form  of  a  lower  rate  of  wages,  longer  hours  of  labor,  or 
worse  conditions  of  sanitation  and  safety,  necessarily  heightens 
the  relative  influence  on  the  contract  of  all  the  elements  that 
are  left.  If  the  conditions  of  employment  are  unregulated,  it 
will  frequently  pay  an  employer  not  to  select  the  best  workman, 
but  to  give  the  preference  to  an  incompetent  or  infirm 
man,  a  "  boozer  "  or  a  person  of  bad  character,  provided  that 
he  can  hire  him  at  a  sufficiently  low  wage,  make  him  work 
excessive  and  irregular  hours,  or  subject  him  to  insanitary  or 
dangerous  conditions.  If  the  employer  cannot  go  below  a 
common  minimum  rate,  and  is  unable  to  grade  the  other 
conditions  of  employment  down  to  the  level  of  the  lowest 
and  most  necessitous  wage-earner  in  his  establishment,  he  is 
economically  impelled  to  do  his  utmost  to  raise  the  level  of 

1  The  Trade  Unionist  conception  and  application  of  a  Standard  Rate  of  re- 
muneration stands,  it  need  hardly  be  said,  at  the  opposite  pole  from  the  mediaeval 
fixing  by  law  of  a  wage  which  it  was  equally  an  offence  to  diverge  from  in  either 
direction.  There  is  no  resemblance  between  the  economic  effects  of  fixing  a 
minimum  wage,  and  those  of  establishing  a  maximum. 


Economic  Characteristics  717 

efficiency  of  all  his  workers  so  as  to  get  the  best  possible 
return  for  the  fixed  conditions.1 

This  is  the  basis  of  the  oft-repeated  accusation  brought 
by  the  sentimental  lady  or  district  visitor  against  the  Trade 
Union  Standard  Rate,  that  it  prevents  an  employer  from  pre- 
ferentially selecting  an  old  man,  or  a  physical  or  moral 
invalid,  when  there  is  a  vacancy  to  be  filled.  But  it  is  clear 
that  the  efficiency  of  industry  is  promoted  by  every  situation 
being  filled  by  the  best  available  candidate.  If  the  old  man 
is  engaged  instead  of  the  man  in  the  prime  of  life,  the  man 
of  irregular  habits  rather  than  the  steady  worker,  there  is  a 
clear  loss  all  round.2  From  the  point  of  view  of  the 
economist,  concerned  to  secure  the  highest  efficiency  of  the 
national  industry,  it  must  be  counted  to  the  credit  of  the 

1  "  The  consequence  is,"  says  Mr.  Lecky,  of  the  Trade  Union  Standard  Rate, 
"  that  the  employer  is  necessarily  driven  to  employ  exclusively  the  most  efficient 
labor"  (Democracy  and  Liberty,  vol.  ii.  p.  347).      It  is  often  supposed  that  this 
effect  of  a  Standard  Rate  is  confined  to  Time  Wages.     But  it  operates  also  when 
(as  is  the  case  among  the  majority  of  Trade  Unionists)  the  Standard  Rate  is  a 
Piecework  List.      Even  if  the  employer  pays  only  in  proportion  to  the  work  done, 
it  is  economically  disadvantageous  to  him  and  to  the  community  that  his  premises, 
machinery,  and  brain-power  should  be  used   short  of  their  maximum  capacity. 
This  effect  is  intensified  with  every  increased  use  of  capital  or  brain-power  in 
industry.      The  economic  compulsion  on  the   cotton  manufacturer  to  select  the 
most   efficient   workman  to  fill  a  vacancy  is  as  much  due  to  the  high  cost  of 
machinery  as  to  the  high  Piecework  List. 

2  If  all  the  fully  competent  workmen  are  already  employed,  and  the  weakling 
or  degenerate  is  the  only  candidate  for  the  vacancy,  he  will  be  taken  on,  as  con- 
stantly happens  when  business  is  very  brisk,  notwithstanding  the  Standard  Rate. 
But  if  an  old  man  or  an  irregular  worker  is,  through  philanthropic  influence  on 
some  employer,  or  through  benevolent  favoritism,  given  a  preference,  the  result 
is,  in   practical  life,   that   some  more  competent  workman  is  left  unemployed. 
Thus,    the    burden   on    the    philanthropist   is  not    lessened.      It    may  even    be 
increased,  for  it  probably  costs  more  to  keep  an  unemployed  workman  in  the 
prime  of  life,  with  full  health  and  activities,  and  family  obligations,  than  it  does 
to  maintain  the  aged.      Nor  does    this  argument  assume,  as  some  may  think, 
any  fixed  "work   fund."       Whatever   the    demand  may  be   for   any  particular 
kind  of  service,  efficiency  requires  that  no  weakling  should  be  employed  until  every 
more  competent  man  is  fully  occupied.     The  hypothetical  case  in  which  whilst 
every  competent  workman  in  the  community  is  fully  employed,  there  is  still  some 
demand  unsupplied,  but  not  enough  to  make  it  worth  while  to  pay  the  Standard 
Rate  to  one  marginal  old  man  or  inferior  worker,  may  be  abandoned  to  the  casuist. 
The  necessary  provision,  both  for  the  temporarily  unemployed  and  the  permanently 
unemployable — a  problem  not  created  by  the  enforcement  of  the  Standard  Rate — 
is  dealt  with  in  a  later  part  of  this  chapter. 


718  Trade  Union  Theory 

Device  of  the  Common  Rule,  that  it  compels  the  employer, 
in  his  choice  of  men  to  fill  vacancies,  to  be  always  striving, 
since  he  cannot  get  a  "  cheap  hand,"  to  exact,  for  the  price 
that  he  has  to  pay,  greater  strength  and  skill,  a  higher 
standard  of  sobriety  and  regular  attendance,  and  a  superior 
capacity  for  responsibility  and  initiative.1 

But  the  rigid  enforcement  of  the  Device  of  the  Common 
Rule  does  more  than  act  as  a  perpetual  stimulus  to  the 
selection  of  the  fittest  men  for  employment.  The  fact  that 
the  employer's  mind  is  constantly  intent  on  getting  the  best 
possible  workmen  silently  and  imperceptibly  reacts  on  the 
wage -earners.  The  young  workman,  knowing  that  he 
cannot  secure  a  preference  for  employment  by  offering  to 
put  up  with  worse  conditions  than  the  standard,  seeks  to 
commend  himself  by  a  good  character,  technical  skill,  and 
general  intelligence.  There  is,  accordingly,  under  a  Common 
Rule,  not  only  a  constant  selection  of  the  most  efficient 
candidates,  but  also  a  positive  stimulus  to  the  whole  class  to 
become  ever  more  efficient.2 

We  strike  here  upon  the  explanation  of  the  paradox,  to 
which  we  have  referred,  that  it  is  not  in  practice  found  to 
militate  against  the  maintenance  of  Common  Rules  by 
Collective  Bargaining  that  a  large  number  of  people  would 
like  to  come  into  the  trade.  If  a  Lancashire  millowner  or 
a  Northumberland  coalowner,  tempted  by  the  large  number 
of  candidates  for  employment,  were  to  engage  a  new  cotton- 

1  Du  Cellier  (Histoire  des  Classes  Laborieuses  en  France,  Paris,   1860),  in 
referring  to  the  great  strikes  which  prevailed  all  over  France  in  the  spring  of 
1791  (pp.  320,  321),  notes  the  effect  of  a  Standard  Rate  in  giving  a  positive  advan- 
tage to  the  efficient  workman  over  the  inefficient.     Most  writers  in   1860  seem 
to  have  assumed  that  its  object  was  to  put  the  lazy  and  inefficient  workman  on  a 
level  with  his  more  industrious  rival. 

2  The  converse  has  often  been  pointed  out  by  those  who  have  studied  the 
influence  of  out-door  relief,  promiscuous  charity,  and  casual  labor.     The  fact  that 
a  man  without  character,  or  of  irregular  habits,  can  get  as  easily  taken  on  as  a 
casual  dock-laborer,  as  the  unemployed  workman  with  the  best  possible  testimonials, 
is  rightly  regarded  as  exercising  a  demoralising  influence  on  all  London  labor.     If 
the  dock-companies  were  compelled  to  give,  say  twenty-four  shillings  a  week  to 
every  laborer  who  entered  their  employment,  they  would  at  once  begin  to  pick 
out  only  those  men  on  whose  regular  attendance  and  faithful  service  they  could 
rely. 


Economic  Characteristics  719 

spinner  or  coal-hewer  on  any  other  terms  than  those  custom- 
ary in  the  trade,  all  the  other  spinners  or  hewers  in  his 
establishment  would  instantly  "  hand  in  their  notices,"  and 
eventually  leave  his  service  in  a  body.  No  "  nibbling  at 
wages,"  or  other  standard  conditions,  would  compensate 
such  an  employer  for  the  loss  in  efficiency  that  would  be 
involved  in  replacing  his  whole  staff  of  spinners  or  hewers 
by  inexperienced  hands.  The  more  "  open "  is  the  trade, 
and  the  more  attractive  are  these  standard  conditions,  the 
more  certain  it  is  that  the  employers  will  find  it  economically 
impossible  to  dispense  with  the  services  of  the  main  body 
of  men  already  in  employment.1  Where  the  minimum  con- 
ditions of  employment  are  fixed  and  uniform,  competition 
takes  the  form  of  raising  the  standard  of  quality,  and  where 
these  minimum  conditions  are  relatively  high,  the  successful 
candidates,  picked  as  they  are,  out  of  a  crowd  of  applicants, 
become  a  very  select  class,  which  can  be  individually 
recruited  but  not  collectively  replaced.  The  progressive 
raising  of  the  Common  Rule,  by  constantly  promoting  the 
"  Selection  of  the  Fittest,"  causes  thus  an  increasing  special- 
isation of  function,  creating  a  distinct  group,  having  a 
Standard  of  Life  and  corporate  traditions  of  its  own  which 
each  recruit  is  glad  enough  to  fall  in  with.  If  we  imagine  a 
community  in  which  each  industry  was  definitely  marked 
off  by  its  own  Common  Rule,  the  strategic  strength  of  the 
workmen  would  be  independent  of  any  restriction  on  the 
choice  of  a  trade.  The  employers  in  each  industry  would 
be  free  to  pick  their  workmen  where  they  chose,  but,  being 
unable  to  go  below  the  minimum  wage,  or  otherwise  degrade 
the  conditions  of  employment,  they  would  be  economically 
compelled  to  select  the  very  best  men  for  the  amount  of  work 
required  to  satisfy  the  demand  of  the  consumers.  A 
newly-arrived  workman  would  equally  be  free  to  accept  any 

1  Hence  the  rare  but  prolonged  general  stoppages  of  work  among  the 
Lancashire  Cotton-spinners  require  no  "picketing."  The  employers  know  that 
they  must  have  the  same  body  of  men  back  again,  and  they  accordingly  do  not 
open  their  mills  until  they  have  come  to  terms.  The  same  may  be  said  of  the 
Coalminers  in  all  well-organised  districts. 


720      .  Trade  Union  Theory 

situation  he  could  get,  in  whatever  trade  he  chose,  but  as 
he  would  find  no  opportunity  of  ousting  a  better  man  by 
offering  to  do  his  work  in  an  inferior  way  at  a  reduced  wage, 
he  would  be  economically  compelled  to  drop  into  the 
particular  occupation  in  which,  under  the  given  distribution 
of  demand  and  the  given  supply  of  special  talent,  his 
additional  labor  would  produce  the  greatest  addition  of 
utility. 

That  the  maintenance  of  a  common  minimum  wage 
should,  of  itself,  automatically  improve  the  quality  of  the 
service  will,  to  many  readers,  seem  a  paradox.  Yet  in  all 
other  cases  this  result  of  the  diversion  of  competition  is  an 
accepted  truism  of  practical  economics.  When  a  middle- 
class  governing  body — a  Town  Council  or  a  railway  company, 
for  instance — needs  a  middle-class  official,  be  he  doctor  or 
architect,  engineer  or  general  manager,  it  invariably  con- 
centrates the  competition  on  quality  by  stopping  it  off  price. 
The  practical  experience  of  business  men  has  taught  them 
that  to  engage  the  doctor  or  general  manager  who  offers  to 
come  for  the  lowest  salary  would  be  a  ruinous  bargain. 
They  accordingly  always  first  fix  the  salary  that  they  will  offer, 
determining  the  amount  according  to  the  Standard  of  Life 
of  the  particular  social  grade  they  seek  to  attract,  and  they 
then  pick  the  best  candidate  who  offers  himself  at  that 
salary.1  The  same  effect  of  a  fixed  price  is  noticed  even  in 
the  sale  of  wares,  though  here  the  fixing  of  price  is  seldom 
free  from  some  element  of  monopoly.  If  rival  producers  of 
goods  are  precluded,  by  custom  or  combination,  from  "  under- 
cutting "  each  other  in  the  price  of  their  wares,  they  devote 
all  their  energies  to  outbidding  each  other  in  the  quality. 
Hence  the  fact  that  the  accepted  price  for  the  morning 
newspaper  in  the  United  Kingdom  has  long  been  uniformly 

1  It  is  interesting  to  note  that  the  suggestion,  often  made  by  inexperienced 
"Labor  members"  of  a  public  body,  that  it  is  absurd  to  offer  the  customary 
high  salary  for  a  brain-working  post,  when  there  are  (t  plenty  of  men  willing  to 
do  the  work  for  less  money,"  is  always  held  up  to  derision  by  their  middle-class 
colleagues — and,  according  to  the  Trade  Unionists'  own  argument,  rightly  so — > 
as  being  a  "penny  wise  and  pound  foolish"  policy. 


Economic  Characteristics  721 

one  penny  in  no  way  limits  the  competition  between  rival 
editors.  What  it  does  is  to  concentrate  the  pressure  on  a 
struggle  to  surpass  in  excellence  of  type  and  paper,  prompt 
and  exclusive  collection  of  news,  brightness  of  literary  style, 
and  every  other  form  of  attractiveness.  So  overpowering 
is  this  impulse  among  railway  companies  that,  in  spite  of 
the  strict  limitation  of  the  number  of  competing  lines,  and 
their  agreements  among  themselves,  the  general  managers 
are  always  trying  to  outbid  each  other  for  public  favor  in 
the  other  ways  that  are  left  open  to  them,  and  the  fact  that 
the  three  separate  railways  between  London  and  the  North 
of  England  agree  to  charge  identical  fares  is  constantly 
raising  the  quality  of  the  service  in  speed,  punctuality,  and 
comfort. 

But  whilst,  in  the  absence  of  any  kind  of  monopoly,  the 
adoption  by  all  producers  of  an  identical  price  automatically 
tends  to  bring  about  an  improvement  in  quality,  there  is,  in 
this  as  in  other  respects,  a  vital  distinction  between  wares  and 
the  workmen  who  produce  them.  In  the  case  of  the  wares, 
the  tendency  to  improvement  springs  from  the  effect  of  the 
Common  Rule  in  shifting  the  pressure  of  competition  from 
price  to  quality.  In  the  case  of  the  workmen — influenced, 
as  we  have  seen,  in  the  same  way  by  the  mere  existence 
of  the  Common  Rule — we  have  also  to  consider  the  effect 
on  the  living  human  being  of  improved  sanitary  conditions, 
shorter  hours  of  labor,  and  more  adequate  wages.  If  unre- 
stricted individual  competition  among  the  wage -earners 
resulted  in  the  universal  prevalence  of  a  high  standard  of 
physical  and  mental  activity,  it  would  be  difficult  to  argue 
that  a  mere  improvement  of  sanitation,  a  mere  shortening  of 
the  hours  of  labor,  or  a  mere  increase  in  the  amount  of  food 
and  clothing  obtained  by  the  workers  or  their  families  would 
of  itself  increase  their  industrial  efficiency.  But,  as  a  matter 
of  fact,  whole  sections  of  the  wage-earners,  unprotected  by 
Factory  Act  or  Collective  Bargaining,  are  habitually  crushed 
down  below  the  level  of  physiological  efficiency.  Even  in  the 
United  Kingdom,  at  least  eight  millions  of  the  population — 
VOL.  II  3  A 


722  Trade  Union  Theory 

over  one  million  of  them,  as  Mr.  Charles  Booth  tells  us,  in 
London  alone — are  at  the  present  time  existing  under  con- 
ditions represented  by  adult  male  earnings  of  less  than  a  pound 
a  week.1  The  unskilled  laborer  who  is  only  half  fed,  whose 
clothing  is  scanty  and  inappropriate  to  the  season,  who  lives 
with  his  wife  and  children  in  a  single  room  in  a  slum  tenement, 
and  whose  spirit  is  broken  by  the  ever-recurring  irregularity 
of  employment,  cannot  by  any  incentive  be  stimulated  to  much 
greater  intensity  of  effort,  for  the  simple  reason  that  his 
method  of  life  makes  him  physiologically  incapable  of  either 
the  physical  or  mental  energy  that  would  be  involved.2  Even 
the  average  mechanic  or  factory  operative,  who  earns  from 
2os.  to  355.  per  week,  seldom  obtains  enough  nourishing 
food,  an  adequate  amount  of  sleep,  or  sufficiently  comfortable 
surroundings  to  allow  him  to  put  forth  the  full  physical  and 
mental  energy  of  which  his  frame  is  capable.  No  middle- 
class  brain-worker  who  has  lived  for  any  length  of  time  in 
households  of  typical  factory  operatives  or  artisans  can  have 
failed  to  become  painfully  aware  of  their  far  lower  standard  of 
nutrition,  clothing,  and  rest,  and  also  of  vitality  and  physical 
and  mental  exertion.3  It  has  accordingly  been  pointed  out 

1  See  Sir  R.    Giffen's   evidence    before   the   Royal   Commission   bn   Labor, 
sitting  as  a  whole,  Questions  6942,  6943  ;  Mr.  Charles  Booth,  Life  and  Labour 
of  the  People,  especially  vol.  ix.  p.  427. 

2  "In  England  now,  want  of  food  is  scarcely  ever  the  direct  cause  of  death  ; 
but  it  is  a  frequent  cause  of  that  general  weakening  of  the  system  which  renders 
it  unable  to  resist  disease  ;  and  it  is  a  chief  cause  of  industrial  inefficiency.   .   .   . 
After  food,  the  next  necessaries  of  life  and  labor  are  clothing,   house-room,  and 
firing ;  when  they  are  deficient  the  mind  becomes  torpid,  and  ultimately  the 
physical  constitution  is  undermined.     When  clothing  is  very  scanty  it  is  generally 
worn  night  and  day ;  and  the  skin  is  allowed  to  be  enclosed  in  a  crust  of  dirt. 
A  deficiency  of  house-room  or  of  fuel  causes  people  to  live  in  a  vitiated  atmo- 
sphere which  is  injurious  to  health  and  vigor.   .   .   .   Rest  is  as  essential  for  the 
growth    of  a    vigorous  population  as    the    more    material    necessities    of  food, 
clothing,   etc."  (Professor  A.   Marshall,  Principles  of  Economics,  3rd  edit.  1895, 
pp.  277,  278  ;  see  also  the  interesting  series  of  illustrative  facts  in  The  Ground- 
work of  Economics,  by  C.  S.  Devas,   London,  1883).     For  M'Culloch's  remarks, 
see,  among  other  references,  section  vii.   of  his  Principles  of  Political  Economy, 
especially  as  to  the  "  Advantages  of  a  High  Rate  of  Wages." 

3  The  rich  and  the  middle-class  seldom  realise  how  scandalously  low  is  the 
standard  of  daily  health  among  the  wage-earners.     Apart  from  actual  disease  or 
disablement,  the  workman  and  his  wife  and  family  are  constantly  suffering  from 
minor  ailments,  brought  about  by  unwholesome  or  deficient  food,  bad  sanitation,  the 


Economic  Characteristics  723 

by  many  economists,  from  J.  R.  M'Culloch  to  Professor 
Marshall,  that,  at  any  rate  so  far  as  the  weakest  and  most 
necessitous  workers  are  concerned,  improved  conditions  of 
employment  would  bring  with  them  a  positive  increase  in 
production.  "A  rise  in  the  Standard  of  Life  for  the  whole 
population,"  we  are  now  expressly  told,  "  will  much  increase 
the  National  Dividend,  and  the  share  of  it  which  accrues  to 
each  grade  and  to  each  trade."  *  We  see,  therefore,  that  the 
Device  of  the  Common  Rule,  so  far  as  the  wage-earner  is 
concerned,  promotes  the  action  of  both  forces  of  evolutionary 
progress  ;  it  tends  constantly  to  the  Selection  of  the  Fittest, 
and  at  the  same  time  provides  both  the  mental  stimulus  and 
the  material  conditions  necessary  for  Functional  Adaptation 
to  a  higher  level  of  skill  and  energy. 

Let  us  now  consider  the  effects  of  the  Device  of  the 
Common  Rule  upon  the  brain-workers,  including  under  this 
term  all  who  are  concerned  in  the  direction  of  industry. 
When  all  the  employers  in  a  trade  find  themselves  precluded, 
by  the  existence  of  a  Common  Rule,  from  worsening  the 
conditions  of  employment — when,  for  instance,  they  are 
legally  prohibited  from  crowding  more  operatives  into  their 
mills  or  keeping  them  at  work  for  longer  hours,  or  when 
they  find  it  impossible,  owing  to  a  strictly  enforced  Piece- 
work List,  to  nibble  at  wages — they  are  driven,  in  their 
competitive  struggle  with  each  other,  to  seek  advantage  in 
other  ways.2  We  arrive,  therefore,  at  the  unexpected  result 

lack  of  sufficient  rest  or  holiday,  and  absence  of  medical  care.  The  brain-worker, 
living  temporarily  in  a  wage-earning  family,  becomes  positively  oppressed  by  the 
constant  suffering,  of  one  member  or  another,  from  toothache  or  sores,  headache 
or  dyspepsia,  and  among  the  women,  also  from  the  dragging  pains  or  chronic 
anaemia  brought  about  by  hard  work  or  exposure  at  improper  times.  In  the 
"Sweated"  industries  it  is  scarcely  too  much  to  say  that  the  state  of  health, 
which  is  normal  among  the  professional  classes  of  the  present  day,  is  almost 
unknown. 

1  Professor  A.  Marshall,  Principles  of  Economics >  3rd  edit.  p.  779. 

2  Thus  Mr.  Mundella  writes  of  the  Standard  List  of  Prices  enforced  by  the 
Nottingham  Hosiery  Board  :   "  Formerly,  in  times  of  depression,    the  greatest 
irregularity  prevailed,  according  to  the  individual  character  of  the   employers. 
The  hard  and  unscrupulous,   trading  on  the  necessities  of  the  workmen,  could 
bring  down  wages  below  a  reasonable  level ;  the  more  considerate  must  either 
follow  suit  or  be  undersold.      Our  Board  has  changed  all  that.     All  now  pay  the 


724  Trade  Union  Theory 

that  the  insistence  by  the  Trade  Union  on  uniform  condi- 
tions of  employment  positively  stimulates  the  invention  and 
adoption  of  new  processes  of  manufacture.  This  has  been 
repeatedly  remarked  by  the  opponents  of  Trade  Unionism. 
Thus  Babbage,  in  1832,  described  in  detail  how  the  inven- 
tion and  adoption  of  new  methods  of  forging  and  welding 
gun-barrels  was  directly  caused  by  the  combined  insistence 
on  better  conditions  of  employment  by  all  the  workmen 
engaged  in  the  old  process.  "  In  this  difficulty,"  he  says, 
"  the  contractors  resorted  to  a  mode  of  welding  the  gun- 
barrel  according  to  a  plan  for  which  a  patent  had  been  taken 
out  by  them  some  years  before  the  event.  It  had  not  then 
succeeded  so  well  as  to  come  into  general  use,  in  consequence 
of  the  cheapness  of  the  usual  mode  of  welding  by  hand  labor , 
combined  with  some  other  difficulties  with  which  the  patentee 
had  had  to  contend.  But  the  stimulus  produced  by  the  com- 
bination of  the  workmen  for  this  advance  of  wages  induced 
him  to  make  a  few  trials,  and  he  was  enabled  to  introduce 
such  a  facility  in  welding  gun-barrels  by  roller,  and  such 
perfection  in  the  work  itself,  that  in  all  probability  very 
few  will  in  future  be  welded  by  hand  -  labor."  *  "Similar 
examples,"  continued  Babbage,  "  must  have  presented  them- 
selves to  those  who  are  familiar  with  the  details  of  our 
manufactories,  but  these  are  sufficient  to  illustrate  one  of  the 
results  of  combinations.  ...  It  is  quite  evident  that  they 
have  all  this  tendency  ;  it  is  also  certain  that  considerable 
stimulus  must  be  applied  to  induce  a  man  to  contrive  a  new 
and  expensive  process  ;  and  that  in  both  these  cases  unless 
the  fear  of  pecuniary  loss  had  acted  powerfully  the  improve- 
ment would  not  have  been  made?  2  The  Lancashire  cotton 
trade  supplied  the  same  generation  with  a  classic  instance  of 

same  price,  and  the  competition  is  not  who  shall  screw  down  wages  the  most,  but 
who  shall  buy  material  best,  and  produce  the  best  article" — Arbitration  as  a 
Means  of  Preventing  Strikes,  by  the  Right  Hon.  A.  J.  Mundella  (Bradford,  1 868), 
P-  15 

1  C.   Babbage,  Economy  of  Manufactures    (London,    1832),   p.   246.      The 
welding  of  tubes  of  all  kinds  is  now  invariably  done  by  machinery — a  fact  which 
may  be  said  to  have  made  possible  the  modern  bicycle. 

2  Ibid.  p.  248. 


Economic  Characteristics  725 

"  Trade  Union  folly  "  of  this  kind.  Almost  every  contem- 
porary observer  declares  that  the  adoption  of  the  "self- 
acting"  mule  was  a  direct  result  of  the  repeated  strikes  of 
the  Cotton -spinners  between  1829  and  1836  to  enforce 
their  Piecework  Lists,  and  that  many  other  improvements 
in  this  industry  sprang  from  the  same  stimulus.  The 
Edinburgh  Review  went  so  far  as  to  say  in  1835  that  "  if 
from  the  discovery  of  the  Spinning  Frame  up  to  the  present, 
wages  had  remained  at  a  level,  and  workers'  coalitions  and 
strikes  had  remained  unknown,  we  can  without  exaggeration 
assert  that  the  industry  would  not  have  made  half  the 
progress." l  And,  coming  down  to  our  own  day,  we  have 
ourselves  had  the  experience  of  being  conducted  over  a 
huge  steel-works  in  the  North  by  the  able  captain  of  industry 
who  is  practically  engaged  in  its  administration,  and  being 
shown  one  improvement  after  another  which  had  been 
devised  and  adopted  expressly  because  the  workmen  engaged 
at  the  old  processes  had,  through  their  powerful  Trade 
Unions,  exacted  high  piecework  rates.  To  the  old  econo- 
mist, accustomed  to  the  handicraftsman's  blind  hostility 
to  machinery,  this  undesigned  result  of  insistence  on  high 
wages  seemed  a  proof  of  the  shortsightedness  of  Trade 
Union  action.  The  modern  student  perceives  that  the  Trade 
Unions,  in  insisting  on  better  conditions  of  employment  than 
would  have  been  yielded  by  Individual  Bargaining,  were 
"  building  better  than  they  knew."  To  the  wage-earners  as 
a  class,  it  is  of  the  utmost  importance  that  the  other  factors 
in  production — capital  and  brain  power — should  always  be 

1  Edinburgh  Review ',  July  1835.  Similarly,  Marx  notes  that  it  was  not 
until  the  employment  of  women  and  young  children  in  mines  was  forbidden  that 
coalowners  introduced  mechanical  traction ;  and  that,  as  the  Inspectors  of 
Factories  report  in  1858,  the  introduction  of  "the  half-time  system  stimulated 
the  invention  of  the  piecing  machine  "  in  woollen  yarn  manufacture,  by  which  a 
great  deal  of  child  labor  was  dispensed  with  ( Capital,  Part  LV.  chap.  xv.  sec.  2, 
vol.  ii.  p.  390  of  English  translation  of  1887).  In  the  Proceedings  of  the 
Institute  of  Mechanical  Engineers^  1895  (p.  346),  "the  great  amount  of 
ingenuity  which  had  recently  been  expended  in  the  charging  and  drawing  of  gas- 
retorts"  by  hydraulic  machinery  was  described  as  "the  direct  result  of  the  labor 
troubles  experienced"  since  the  formation  of  the  Gas  Workers'  Union,  and  "it 
showed  what  was  the  general  tendency  of  such  troubles, " 


726  Trade  Union  Theory 

at  their  highest  possible  efficiency,  in  order  that  the  common 
product,  on  which  wages  no  less  than  profits  depend,  may  be 
as  large  as  possible.  The  enforcement  of  the  Common  Rule 
on  all  establishments  concentrates  the  pressure  of  competi- 
tion on  the  brains  of  the  employers,  and  keeps  them  always 
on  the  stretch.  "  Mankind,"  says  Emerson,  "  is  as  lazy  as  it 
dares  to  be,"  and  so  long  as  an  employer  can  meet  the 
pressure  of  the  wholesale  trader,  or  of  foreign  competition, 
by  nibbling  at  wages  or  "  cribbing  time,"  he  is  not  likely  to 
undertake  the  "  intolerable  toil  of  thought,"  that  would  be 
required  to  discover  a  genuine  improvement  in  the  pro- 
ductive process,  or  even,  as  Babbage  candidly  admits,  to 
introduce  improvements  that  have  already  been  invented. 
Hence  the  mere  existence  of  the  Common  Rule,  by  debar- 
ring the  hard-pressed  employer  from  the  most  obvious  source 
of  relief,  positively  drives  him  to  other  means  of  lowering 
the  cost  of  production.  And  the  fact  that  the  Common 
Rule  habitually  brings  to  the  operatives  a  greater  reward 
for  their  own  labor,  itself  further  increases  the  employer's 
incentive  to  adopt  labor-saving  machinery.  For  "  the  lower 
the  day  wage,"  we  are  told,  "  the  smaller  the  rate  of  improve- 
ment in  labor-saving  methods  and  machinery.  .  .  .  Where 
labor  is  cheapest,  the  progress  is  the  slowest." *  Far  from 
being  an  advantage  to  industry,  "  the  cheapness  of  human 
labor  where  it  prevails  is  the  greatest  incentive  for  the  per- 
petuation of  obsolete  methods.  .  .  .  The  incentive  is  want- 
ing for  replacing,  with  large  capital  outlay,  old  and  obsolete 
by  new  and  improved  machinery.  The  survival  of  the 
fittest  is,  therefore,  so  to  speak,  the  result  of  a  high  wage 
rate," 2  provided,  that  is  to  say,  that  the  high  rate  is  enforced 
on  all  establishments  alike.  This  is  now  seen  even  by  the 
capitalists  themselves.  "  We  employers,"  lately  declared  one 
of  the  leading  captains  of  English  industry,  "  owe  more  than, 
as  a  body,  we  are  inclined  to  admit,  to  the  improvements  in 
our  methods  of  manufacture  due  to  the  firmness  and  independ- 

1   The  Economy  of  High  Wages,  by  J.  Schoenhof  (New  York,  1892),  p.  276. 
2  Ibid.  pp.  38,  39. 


Economic  Characteristics  727 

ence  of  trade  combinations.  Our  industrial  steadiness  and 
enterprise  are  the  envy  of  the  world.  The  energy  and 
pertinacity  of  Trade  Unions  have  caused  Acts  of  Parlia- 
ment to  be  passed  which  would  not  otherwise  have  been 
promoted  by  employers  or  politicians,  all  of  which  have 
tended  to  improve  British  Commerce.1  .  .  .  Every  intelligent 
employer  will  admit  that  his  factory  or  workshop,  when 
equipped  with  all  the  comforts  and  conveniences  and  pro- 
tective appliances  prescribed  by  Parliament  for  the  benefit 
and  protection  of  his  workpeople — though  great  effort,  and, 
it  may  be,  even  sacrifice,  on  his  part  has  been  made  to 
procure  them — has  become  a  more  valuable  property  in 
every  sense  of  the  word,  and  a  profit  has  accrued  to  him 
owing  to  the  improved  conditions  under  which  his  work- 
people have  been  placed."  2 

Besides  this  direct  effect  in  stimulating  all  the  employers, 
the  mere  existence  of  the  Common  Rule  has  another,  and 
even  more  important  result  on  the  efficiency  of  industry, 
in  that  it  is  always  tending  to  drive  business  into  those 
establishments  which  are  most  favorably  situated,  best 
equipped,  and  managed  with  the  greatest  ability,  and  to 

1  A  recent  instance  is  afforded  by  the  humble  industiy  of  washing  clothes. 
The  chairman  of  the  Eastbourne  Sanitary  Steam  Laundry  Company,  Limited, 
told  his  shareholders  on  25th  January   1897  that   "the  new  Factory  Act  pre- 
vented the  hands  working  so  long  as  they  used  to  do,  and  the  directors  had  been 
obliged  to  provide  machinery  to  enable  them  to   do   the   work   in  less   time " 
(Laundjy  Record,  ist  March  1897).     The  extraordinary  backwardness  of  the  art  of 
washing  clothes,    and    the   difficulty  of  obtaining  skilled,    regular,   and  honest 
laundry  workers,  are,  we  suggest,  largely  due  to  the  lack  of  stimulus  to  employers 
and   of  decent  conditions    for  the  workpeople,   resulting  from   the   absence   of 
Common  Rules. 

2  W.   Mather,  Contemporary  Review,  November   1892.      Here  Mr.   Mather 
has  the  economists  of  to-day  on  his  side.      Professor  Nicholson  cites  Thorold 
Rogers  as  observing,  "  that  every  act  of  the  legislature  that  seems  to  interfere 
with  the  doctrine  of  Laisser  Faire,  and  has  stood  the  test  of  experience,  has 
been  endorsed  because  it  has  added  to  the  general  efficiency  of  labor"  (Rogers, 
Six  Centuries  of  Work  and  Wages,  London,  1891,  p.   528;  Nicholson,  Prin- 
ciples of  Political  Economy,  Edinburgh,  1893,  ?•   331)'      Mr.   Mather,  who  is  at 
the  head   of  a  great  engineering  establishment,  is  the  author  of  the  following 
interesting  pamphlets  :   The  Forty-eight  Hours'  Week :  a  Year's  Experiment  and 
its  Results  at  the  Salford  Iron    Works  (Manchester,    1894) ;    A  Reply  to  some 
Criticisms  on  Mr.  Mathers  Report  of  a  Year's  Trial  of  the  Forty -eight  Hours'  Week 
(London,  1894). 


728  Trade  Union  Theory 

eliminate  the  incompetent  or  old-fashioned  employer.  This 
fact,  patent  to  the  practical  man,  was  not  observed  by  the 
older  economists.  Misled  by  their  figment  of  the  equality 
of  profits,  they  seem  habitually  to  have  assumed  that  an 
increase  in  the  cost  of  production  would  be  equally  injurious 
to  all  the  employers  in  the  trade.  The  modern  student  at 
once  recognises  that  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule,  from 
its  very  nature,  must  always  fail  to  get  at  the  equivalent  of 
all  differential  advantages  of  productive  agents  above  the 
level  of  the  worst  actually  required  at  any  given  time. 
When,  for  instance,  the  Amalgamated  Association  of 
Operative  Cotton -spinners  secures  uniform  piecework  lists, 
identical  hours  of  labor,  and  similar  precautions  against 
accident  and  disease  in  all  English  cotton  mills,  it  in  no 
way  encroaches  upon  the  extra  profits  earned  by  firms  of 
long-standing  reputation  for  quality,  exceptional  commercial 
skill,  or  technical  capacity.  Similarly,  it  does  nothing  to 
deprive  mills  enjoying  a  special  convenience  of  site,  the 
newest  and  best  machinery,  valuable  patent  rights  or  trade 
connections,  of  the  exceptional  profits  due  to  these  advan- 
tages. This  is  still  more  apparent  in  the  case  of  the  coal- 
miners,  whose  Mines  Regulation  Acts  and  "county  averages" 
of  wages,  applying  equally  all  round,  necessarily  leave 
untouched  the  vast  incomes  derived  from  the  mining 
royalties  of  all  but  the  worst  mine  in  use.  The  very  nature 
of  this  fundamental  device  of  Trade  Unionism — the  neces- 
sary uniformity  of  any  rule  that  is  to  be  common  to  the 
whole  trade — compels  it  to  be  fixed  with  reference  to  the 
circumstances,  not  of  the  best,  but  of  the  worst  establish- 
ment at  which  the  Trade  Unionists  wish  to  obtain  employ- 
ment. This  does  not  mean  that,  in  any  well-organised  trade, 
the  Standard  Rate,  or  other  Common  Rule,  will  be  fixed  so 
as  to  enable  the  economically  weakest  employers  to  con- 
tinue in  business.  On  the  contrary,  it  is  a  matter  of 
common  experience  that  every  time  a  Trade  Union  really 
secures  a  Common  Rule,  whether  by  Collective  Bargaining 
or  Legal  Enactment,  it  knocks  another  nail  into  the  coffin 


Economic  Characteristics  729 

of  the  least  intelligent  and  worst-equipped  employers  in  the 
trade.1  We  have  already  described  how  the  small  masters 
in  the  boot  and  shoe  industry  denounce,  as  a  conspiracy 
of  the  great  capitalists  in  the  trade,  any  acceptance  of  a 
"  uniform  statement,"  or  of  the  high  standard  of  workshop 
accommodation  insisted  on  by  the  National  Union  of  Boot 
and  Shoe  Operatives.  In  the  building  trades,  it  is  the 
small  "jerry  masters"  who  especially  protest  against  the 
"  tyranny  "  of  the  "  Working  Rules,"  to  which  the  contractor 
in  a  large  way  of  business  willingly  agrees.  And  in  Lanca- 
shire, it  is  in  the  backward  villages,  where  many  of  the 
mills  are  already  shut  up,  that  Factory  Acts  and  Piecework 
Lists  are  denounced  for  the  relentless  pressure  with  which 
they  force  up  the  standard  of  efficiency  to  the  level  of 
Oldham  or  Bolton.2 

How  far  this  policy  of  the  "  selection  of  the  fittest " 
among  employers  can  be  carried  at  any  particular  time  is 
a  matter  for  delicate  calculation.  It  is  obviously  to  the 

1  "  We  have  been  working  at  a  loss  for  years,"  said  a  large  cotton  manu- 
facturer to  the  Union  secretary.     "  Yes,"  was  the  shrewd  reply,  "you  have  been 
losing  your  little  mills  and  building  bigger  ones." — First  Prize  Essay  on  Trades 
Unions,  by  "Ithuriel"  (Glasgow,  1875),  p.  31. 

2  This   is  a  matter  of  deliberate    policy   with    the    modern    Trade    Union. 
Thus,  the  official  organ  of  the  Cotton  Operatives  lately  declared,  in  an  article 
written  by  a    prominent  Trade  Union  official,  that   "if  a  firm  realises  that  it 
cannot  manufacture  with  profit  to  itself,  and  it  is  paying  no  more  than  others  for 
labor,  it  is  better  that  that  firm,  harsh  though  the  doctrine  may  seem,  should 
cease  to  exist,  rather  than  the  operatives  should  accept  a  reduction  in  wages  and 
drag  the  whole  trade  down  with  them."—  Cotton  Factory  Times  >  i;th  July  1896. 

This  result  is  then  often  pointed  to  as  showing  the  folly  of  Trade  Union 
action  in  "  driving  capital  out  of  the  trade."  But,  so  long  as  any  better-managed, 
better-equipped,  or  more  favorably  situated  mill  is  capable  of  doing  increased 
business,  the  amount  of  effective  capital  in  the  trade  will  not  be  lessened  through 
the  closing  of  the  worst  mill.  The  price  remaining  the  same,  and  therefore 
presumably  the  demand,  the  same  quantity  of  the  product  will  be  produced  and 
sold.  All  that  will  have  happened  will  be  that  the  capital  in  the  trade  will,  on 
an  average,  be  employed  to  greater  advantage.  How  much  scope  there  is,  in 
modern  industry,  for  this  concentration  of  business  in  the  most  advantageous 
centres,  may  be  judged  from  the  admirable  Statistics  of  Manufactures  of  Massa- 
chusetts from  1886  to  1896,  which  show  that,  in  the  two  or  three  thousand 
separate  establishments  investigated,  the  average  business  done  was  only  between 
50  to  70  per  cent  of  their  full  productive  capacity — in  some  trades  less  than  half 
the  possible  output  of  the  existing  plant  being  made. — See  the  Eleventh  Report, 
Boston,  1897,  pp.  99-104,  169. 


730  Trade  Union  Theory 

interest  of  the  Trade  Union  so  to  fix  the  Common 
Rule  as  to  be  constantly  "weeding  out"  the  old-fashioned 
or  stupid  firms,  and  to  concentrate  the  whole  production 
in  the  hands  of  the  more  efficient  "  captains  of  industry," 
who  know  how  to  lower  the  cost  of  the  product  without 
lowering  the  wage.  Thus,  so  long  as  the  more  advan- 
tageously situated  establishments  in  the  trade  are  not 
working  up  to  their  utmost  capacity,  or  can,  without  losing 
their  advantage,  be  further  enlarged,  the  Trade  Union 
could  theoretically  raise  its  Common  Rule,  to  the  successive 
exclusion,  one  after  another,  of  the  worst  employers,  without 
affecting  price  or  the  consumers'  demand,  and  therefore 
without  diminishing  the  area  of  employment.  By  thus 
"  raising  the  margin  of  cultivation,"  and  simultaneously 
increasing  the  output  of  the  more  advantageously  situated 
establishments,  this  Device  of  the  Common  Rule  may 
accordingly  shift  the  boundary  of  that  part  of  the  produce 
which  is  economically  of  the  nature  of  rent,  and  put  some  of 
it  into  the  pockets  of  the  workmen.1  If,  for  instance,  one 
employer  owns  a  patent  which  greatly  reduces  the  cost  of 
production,  he  will  be  able,  so  long  as  his  output  amounts 
only  to  a  portion  of  the  quantity  demanded  by  the  public  at 
the  old  price,  to  put  into  his  own  pocket  the  entire  equivalent 
of  the  improvement.  But  if  the  Trade  Union,  by  gradually 
raising  its  Standard  Rate,  drives  all  the  other  employers  one 
by  one  out  of  the  trade,  and  concentrates  the  whole  business 
into  its  most  advantageous  centre,  the  aggregate  cost  of 
production  will  be  thereby  greatly  reduced.  If  the  increased 
profit  is  retained  by  the  monopolist,  there  is  no  theoretic 
reason  why  the  workmen,  if  they  are  strong  enough,  should 
not  encroach  on  this  surplus,  until  they  had  reduced  it  to 
the  current  rate  of  profit  of  capital.  There  are,  however, 
practical  limits  to  such  a  process.  However  advantageously 

1  Ricardo  and,  more  explicitly,  J.  S.  Mill  pointed  out  that  anything  which 
increased  the  output  of  the  more  fertile  farms  would  tend  to  reduce  the  aggregate 
rent  of  agricultural  land. — Principles  of  Political  Economy ,  Book  IV.  ch.  iii.  §  4, 
pp.  434-436  of  1865  edition. 


Economic  Characteristics  731 

situated  a  particular  establishment  may  be,  we  do  not 
find  that  it,  in  practice,  absorbs  the  whole  trade.  Con- 
siderations of  locality  and  connection,  of  variety  of 
demand,  of  the  lack  of  capital,  and,  above  all,  the  absence 
of  desire  or  capacity  to  manage  a  larger  business, 
set  limits  to  the  indefinite  extension  of  even  the  most 
advantageously  placed  firm.1  And  whilst  these  limits 
interfere  with  the  concentration  of  industry,  other  considera- 
tions conspire  to  hinder  the  desire  of  the  Trade  Union  to 
push  to  the  uttermost  its  policy  of  "  levelling  up."  Though 
it  would  immediately  profit  the  trade  as  a  whole,  and 
ultimately  even  its  weakest  members,  the  concentration 
involves,  to  begin  with,  a  painful  wrench  for  those  members 
who  would  have  to  change  their  methods  of  working,  often 
alter  their  habits  of  life,  and  sometimes  even  migrate  to  a 
new  town.  In  such  trades  as  the  Engineers,  the  Boot  and 
Shoe  Operatives,  the  Cotton-weavers,  and  the  Compositors, 
the  Trade  Union  has,  for  whole  generations,  been  struggling 
to  induce  its  most  apathetic  and  conservative  -  minded 
members  to  put  on  the  adaptability  and  mobility  of  the 
"  economic  man."  The  growth  of  "  uniform  lists "  and 
"  national  agreements  "  in  one  trade  after  another  is  a  sign 
that  this  difficulty  is,  in  some  cases,  being  overcome  ;  whilst 
part  of  the  increasing  preference  for  the  Method  of  Legal 
Enactment  is,  in  our  view,  to  be  attributed  to  the  fact  that 
it  presses  uniformly  on  all  districts,  and  thus  positively 
favors  the  concentration  of  each  industry  in  the  centres  in 
which  it  can  most  advantageously  be  carried  on.  It  is 
among  the  Lancashire  Cotton-spinners  that  this  far-sighted 
policy  has  been  pursued  with  the  greatest  persistency,  with 
the  result,  if  we  may  believe  the  employers,  of  transferring 
to  the  operatives,  in  higher  wages  and  better  conditions,  no 
small  share  of  each  successive  improvement  in  production. 

1  For  an  expansion  of  this  idea  see  "The  Rate  of  Interest  and  the  Laws  of 
Distribution,"  by  Sidney  Webb,  in  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  April  1888. 
Thus,  it  cannot  be  assumed  that  the  cost  of  the  marginal  production  is  equal  in 
good  and  bad  establishments  alike.  Many  other  causes  than  marginal  cost  of 
production  determine  the  distribution  of  business. 


732  Trade  Union  Theory 

This  result  of  the  Common  Rule — the  constant  selection 
of  the  fittest  among  the  directors  of  industry,  and  the  con- 
centration of  business  in  the  most  advantageous  centres — is, 
strangely  enough,  often  made  a  matter  of  reproach  to  Trade 
Unionism.  Thus,  even  so  benevolent  an  employer  as  Sir 
Benjamin  Browne,  looking  back  after  twenty -six  years* 
experience  of  the  Engineers'  fixing  of  a  Nine  Hours'  Normal 
Day  in  1871,  blames  the  Trade  Unions  for  thereby  driving 
business  into  the  hands  of  the  best-equipped  firms.  "  From 
this  time,"  he  declares,  "  more  was  done  by  large  companies 
and  less  by  small  employers,  .  .  .  more  and  more  costly 
and  complicated  machinery  was  introduced.  .  .  .  The 
practical  effect  of  the  Nine  Hours'  Movement  was  to  ruin 
the  small  employer." 1  But  seeing  that  the  aggregate 
volume  of  engineering  work  has  admittedly  not  fallen  off 
— that  it  has,  on  the  contrary,  enormously  increased — it 
cannot  but  be  regarded  as  an  economic  gain  that  this  work 
should  be  executed  where  it  can  be  done  to  the  greatest 
advantage.  If,  in  the  absence  of  a  Common  Rule,  the 
"  small  employer,"  with  his  imperfect  machinery  and  in- 
sufficient capital,  with  inferior  scientific  training  and  inade- 
quate knowledge  of  the  markets,  is  enabled  to  divert  business 
from  superior  establishments  by  nibbling  at  wages,  requiring 
systematic  overtime,  overcrowding  his  factory,  or  neglecting 
precautions  against  accident,  his  existence  is  not  only  de- 
trimental to  the  operatives,  but  also  a  clear  diminution  of 
the  nation's  productive  efficiency.  Hence  the  enforcement 
of  a  Common  Rule,  by  progressively  eliminating  the  worst 
equipped  employers  and  concentrating  the  whole  pressure  of 
competition  on  securing  the  utmost  possible  efficiency  of 
production,  tends  constantly  to  the  development  of  the 
highest  type  of  industrial  organisation.2 

1  Letter  to  the  Times  of  nth  August  1897. 

2  The  student  will  find  an  interesting  confirmation  of  much  of  the  preceding 
analysis,  with  illustrations  drawn  from  the  industry  of  to-day,  in  an  able  address 
just  delivered  by  a  leading  employer  in  the  engineering  trade.      The  Inaugural 
Address  by  the  President  of  the  Manchester  Association  of  Engineers  (Mr.  Joseph 
Nasmith),  published  at  Manchester  (1897),  is  largely  occupied  with  the  means 


Economic  Characteristics  733 

Thus,  the  effect  of  the  Common  Rule  on  the  organisation 
of  industry,  like  its  effect  on  the  manual  laborer,  and  the 
brain-working  entrepreneur,  is  all  in  the  direction  of  increas- 
ing efficiency.  It  in  no  way  abolishes  competition,  or  lessens 
its  intensity.  What  it  does  is  perpetually  to  stimulate  the 
selection  of  the  most  efficient  workmen,  the  best-equipped 
employers,  and  the  most  advantageous  forms  of  industry.  It 
in  no  way  deteriorates  any  of  the  factors  of  production  ;  on 
the  contrary,  its  influence  acts  as  a  constant  incentive  to  the 
further  improvement  of  the  manual  laborers,  the  machinery, 

by  which  English  employers  can  best  meet  foreign  competition.  He  distinguishes 
three  factors  of  supreme  importance,  among  them  being  neither  low  wages  nor 
long  hours.  "First,  the  economic  effect  of  improved  appliances;  second,  the 
adoption  of  the  best  commercial  methods ;  and  third,  the  fullest  development  of 
the  skill  of  all  those  engaged  in  an  industry,  and  especially  of  the  leaders.  .  .  . 
One  of  the  direct  consequences  of  the  adoption  of  the  newer  methods  and 
appliances  has  been  such  a  subdivision  of  some  operations  as  to  involve  a  fresh 
organisation  of  labor.  Instances  will  be  well  known  in  which  the  making  of  a 
single  article,  as,  for  instance,  the  matrix  used  in  the  linotype  machine,  or  the 
spindles  which  are  made  for  ring-spinning  machines,  involves  the  handling  of 
the  article  by  fifteen  or  twenty  workpeople,  each  of  whom  is  charged  with  the 
performance  of  one  operation,  forming  possibly  a  small  portion  of  those  which 
are  needed  to  complete  the  whole  article.  This  necessitates  the  design  and 
employment  of  a  large  number  of  machines  or  appliances,  each  of  which  is 
intended  to  aid  in  effecting  one  of  these  minor  operations,  and  calling  for  the 
attention  of  a  workman  specially  trained  in  its  iise.  In  this  way  there  has  been 
silently  worked  a  revolution  which  is  not  always  fully  appreciated  even  yet,  and 
"which  has  had  no  less  an  effect  than  the  elevation  of  the  machine  tender  from  a 
subordinate  to  an  important  position  in  the  economy  of  a  workshop.  It  is  in 
consequence  of  the  facility  of  subdivision  which  the  ingenuity  displayed  in  the 
production  of  special  appliances  has  brought  about,  that  in  all  organised 
industries  the  labor  cost  of  any  article  continually  tends  to  decrease.  Probably 
because  the  economic  change  which  has  taken  place  has  only  been  partially 
appreciated,  we  find  people  still  making  a  great  fuss  about  wages.  As  a  matter 
of  fact  the  rate  of  wages  is  not  necessarily  a  guide  to  the  labor  cost  of  an  article, 
and  a  wider  recognition  of  this  fact  would  prevent  a  good  deal  of  trouble.  .  .  . 
Labor  cost  and  not  wages  is  the  determining  factor,  and  there  is  not  necessarily 
a  direct  connection  between  them.  Indeed,  it  may  be  asserted  that  they  are 
often  in  inverse  proportion,  and  that  the  more  highly  organised  an  industry  is, 
the  greater  is  the  tendency  for  that  to  be  so.  .  .  .  Nothing  has  so  much  influence 
upon  this  problem  as  the  possibility  of  making  articles  in  large  numbers,  and  it 
is  in  this  direction  that  much  remains  to  be  done  by  engineers.  Nothing 
presents  so  hopeful  a  field  for  the  future  efforts  of  constructive  engineers  as  the 
design  and  manufacture  of  machines  which  will  enable  the  manufacturers  to 

k produce  all  kinds  of  articles  in  the  greatest  possible  numbers  in  any  given  time. 
Wages  become  a  secondary  consideration  under  these  circtimstances,  and  although 
i  change  in  the  rate  paid  may  for  a  time  affect  the  economic  conditions,  it  is  not 
'ong  before  the  skill  of  the  constructor  has  placed  him  abreast  of  the  new  conditions." 


734  Trade  Union  Theory 

and  the  organising  ability  used  in  industry.  In  short, 
whether  with  regard  to  Labor  or  Capital,  invention  or  organ- 
ising ability,  the  mere  existence  of  a  uniform  Common  Rule 
in  any  industry  promotes  alike  the  selection  of  the  most 
efficient  factors  of  production,  their  progressive  functional 
adaptation  to  a  higher  level,  and  their  combination  in  the 
most  advanced  type  of  industrial  organisation.1  And  these 
results  are  permanent  and  cumulative.  However  slight  may 
be  the  effect  upon  the  character  or  physical  efficiency  of  the 
wage-earner  or  the  employer  ;  however  gradual  may  be  the 
improvement  in  processes  or  in  the  organisation  of  the 
industry,  these  results  endure  and  go  on  intensifying  them- 
selves so  that  the  smallest  step  forward  becomes,  in  time, 
an  advance  of  the  utmost  importance. 

So  far  the  substitution  in  any  trade  of  the  Common 
Rule  for  the  anarchy  of  Individual  Bargaining  would  seem 
to  be  in  every  way  beneficial.  We  have  now  to  consider 
some  characteristics  which  lead  to  a  qualification  of  this 
conclusion. 

We  have  to  note,  in  the  first  place,  that  the  result,  though 
certain,  may  probably  be  slow.  The  passing  of  a  Factory 
Act  enforcing  a  definite  standard  of  sanitation  or  a  normal 
day,  may  be  indispensable  to  prevent  the  progressive  de- 
gradation of  whole  classes  of  operatives ;  by  its  diversion  of 
the  pressure  of  competition  it  may  re-establish  the  physique, 
improve  the  character,  and  increase  the  efficiency  of  all  sub- 
sequent generations  ;  but  the  very  day  it  comes  into  opera- 
tion it  will  almost  certainly  raise  the  cost  of  labor  to  the 
employer,  if  only  for  a  time.  The  extension  of  a  uniform 
Piecework  List  to  all  the  establishments  in  an  industry  may 
eventually  concentrate  all  the  business  in  the  best-equipped 

1  The  influence  of  a  Common  Rule  in  changing  the  nature  and  effects  of  com- 
petition in  industry,  is,  of  course,  not  confined  to  the  relation  between  employer 
and  workmen.  The  respective  results  on  the  character  and  efficiency  of  pro- 
duction, of  "complete  freedom  of  enterprise,"  on  the  one  hand,  and  of  such 
uniform  restrictions  as  the  Adulteration  Acts,  the  by-laws  relating  to  the  con- 
struction of  buildings,  or  the  regulations  for  the  conduct  of  common  lodging- 
houses  on  the  other,  are  well  worth  further  study  from  this  point  of  view. 


Economic  Characteristics  735 

mills,  managed  by  the  most  capable  employers,  and  thus 
positively  reduce  the  cost  of  production  ;  but  its  first  effect 
will  probably  be  to  raise  that  cost  in  the  old-fashioned  or 
outlying  establishments  not  yet  dispensed  with.  Like  all 
permanent  changes  in  personal  character  or  social  organisa- 
tion, the  economic  effects  of  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule 
are  gradual  in  their  operation,  and  will  not  instantly  reveal 
themselves  in  an  improvement  of  quality  or  a  diminished 
cost  of  production. 

The  response,  moreover,  in  the  way  of  added  efficiency 
will  vary  from  trade  to  trade.  The  rapidity  with  which  the 
response  will  be  given,  the  extent  to  which  the  improvement 
can  be  carried,  and  the  particular  "  curve  of  diminishing 
return "  that  it  will  describe,  will  differ  in  each  industry 
according  as  its  condition  at  the  moment  affords  more  or  less 
scope  for  the  operation  of  the  two  potent  forces  of  Functional 
Adaptation  and  the  Selection  of  the  Fittest,  on  workmen  and 
capitalists  respectively.  Thus,  the  effect  of  the  constant 
selection  among  the  operatives  will  vary  according  to 
the  range  of  choice  which  the  technical  circumstances  of 
the  industry  permit  the  employer  to  exercise.  This 
depends,  in  practice,  for  the  skilled  trades,  upon  the  extent 
to  which  the  process  itself  requires  the  co-operation  of 
boys  or  other  learners,  from  whom  the  skilled  workers  are 
recruited.  Hence,  the  mule- spinners,  attended  each  by  two 
piecers — ten  times  the  proportion  of  learners  required  to 
keep  up  the  trade — are  a  far  more  "  selected  "  class  than  the 
skilled  hand-working  tailors  of  the  West  End  trade,  who 
need  have  no  boys  at  all  working  by  their  side,  and  who  are 
largely  assisted  by  women  incapable  of  replacing  them.  We 
do  not  wish  to  discuss  the  social  expediency  of  an  arrange- 
ment, which  attracts  into  an  occupation  every  year  thousands 
of  boys,  nine-tenths  of  whom,  after  they  have  reached 
maturity,  find  themselves  skilled  in  an  occupation  which  they 
have  no  chance  of  following,  and  which  they  must  perforce 
abandon,  at  one  period  of  their  life  or  another,  for  some  new 
means  of  livelihood.  But  whatever  may  be  the  consequences 


736  Trade  Union  Theory 

of  this  arrangement  to  the  unsuccessful  piecers,  its  effect  on 
the  cotton -spinners,  as  a  class,  is  to  make  them  a  highly 
selected  aristocracy  of  ability,  able  to  adapt  themselves  to 
the  progressive  complication  and  "speeding-up"  of  the 
machinery.  Analogous  differences  exist  between  trade  and 
trade  in  regard  to  the  extent  to  which  Selection  of  the 
Fittest  can  act  on  the  employers,  especially  as  to  machinery 
and  location.  Thus,  the  total  absence  of  any  form  of 
monopoly  in  cotton -spinning  and  cotton -weaving,  and  the 
remarkable  facility  and  cheapness  with  which  Lancashire 
capital  can  always  be  obtained  for  new  cotton  mills,  gives 
the  cotton  Trade  Unions  a  special  opportunity  for  increasing 
the  efficiency  of  the  industry,  by  constantly  driving  out  the 
weakest  firms.  A  complete  contrast  to  this  state  of  things 
is  presented  by  such  legal  or  natural  monopolies  as  railways, 
waterworks,  tramways,  and  gas  works,  where  the  Trade 
Unions  have  to  put  up  with  whatever  incompetent  Board  of 
Directors  or  General  Manager  may  happen  to  hold  the  field. 
Nor  is  the  difference  between  trade  and  trade  any  less  in 
regard  to  the  action  on  the  employers  of  Functional  Adapta- 
tion. Thus,  the  factory  boot  and  shoe  industry,  supplied 
almost  day  by  day  with  fresh  inventions,  and  constantly 
recruited  by  the  upstarting  of  new  businesses,  offers  obviously 
more  scope  for  the  improvements  caused  by  pressure  on  the 
brains  of  employers,  than  an  industry  like  English  agriculture, 
where  generation  often  succeeds  to  generation  in  the  same 
farm,  and  economic  freedom  of  enterprise  and  mobility  of 
capital  is  comparatively  rare.  The  only  direction  in  which 
progress  could  be  at  all  equal  as  between  trade  and  trade 
seems  to  be  the  improvement  of  the  operatives,  brought 
about  by  increased  food,  clothing,  and  rest.  Even  in  this 
respect  there  would  be  more  scope  for  improvement  in  an 
industry  carried  on  by  women  or  unskilled  laborers,  who  are 
likely  to  be  chronically  underfed  or  overworked,  than  in  a 
trade  employing  skilled  artisans  already  earning  a  high 
Standard  Rate.  But  once  the  process  of  "  levelling  up  "  had 
reached  a  certain  point,  this  inequality  of  response  would 


Economic  Characteristics  737 

cease  to  be  apparent.  At  this  stage,  the  increase  in 
efficiency  due  to  improvement  in  physical  health  and  vigor, 
like  the  increase  in  mental  activity  made  possible  by  suffi- 
ciency of  food  and  rest,  might  be  expected,  in  all  trades, 
to  bear  a  fairly  close  relation  to  the  improvement  in  the 
workers'  conditions,  and  would  probably  be  subject  to  much 
the  same  limits  in  all  the  industries  of  a  particular  country. 
In  every  other  respect  trade  differs  widely  from  trade  in  the 
rapidity  and  degree  with  which  it  responds  in  the  way 
of  added  efficiency,  to  the  stimulus  of  the  Common  Rule. 
And  this  difference  between  one  trade  and  another,  in  the 
potentiality  of  increased  efficiency,  bears,  it  will  be  obvious, 
no  definite  relation  to  the  strategic  strength  or  political 
power  of  the  operatives.  Whether  the  workers  in  any 
particular  trade  will  actually  be  able  to  extract  from  the 
employers,  either  by  Mutual  Insurance,  Collective  Bargaining, 
or  Legal  Enactment,  higher  wages,  shorter  hours,  or  improved 
sanitation,  depends,  in  practice,  on  many  other  circumstances 
than  those  affecting  the  possibilities  of  increased  efficiency. 
Indeed,  if  we  could  admit  any  generalisation  at  all  on  the 
point,  we  might  infer,  from  the  general  "  law  of  diminishing 
returns,"  that  a  trade  in  which  the  wage -earners  have 
hitherto  been  too  weak  to  obtain  any  Common  Rule,  would 
be  likely  to  yield  a  greater  harvest  of  added  efficiency  than 
an  old-established,  well-organised,  and  powerful  industry,  in 
which  the  Trade  Union  had,  for  generations  past,  pushed 
its  advantages  to  the  utmost,  and  so  probably  exhausted 
most  of  the  stimulus  to  increased  Functional  Adaptation  and 
Selection  of  the  Fittest  produced  by  the  use  of  the  Common 
Rule. 

There  will,  accordingly,  be  at  any  particular  moment  a 
practical  limit  to  the  advantageous  raising  of  the  Common 
Rule.  The  Selection  of  the  Fittest,  whether  of  employers, 
workmen,  establishments,  or  districts,  can  achieve  no  more 
than  to  take  the  best  for  the  purpose  that  the  community  at 
the  time  supplies.  Functional  Adaptation,  whether  of  work- 
men or  employers,  or  their  mutual  organisation,  can  go  no 
VOL.  II  3  B 


738  Trade  Union  Theory 

further  than  the  structure  for  the  time  being  allows.  And 
though  each  successive  rise  in  the  Common  Rule  may  pro- 
duce its  own  increment  of  additional  efficiency,  there  is  a 
rapidly  decreasing  return  to  each  successive  application  of 
pressure.  Hence  a  Trade  Union  which  has,  in  the  first  few 
years  of  its  complete  organisation,  succeeded  in  obtaining 
considerable  advances  in  its  Standard  Rate,  sensible  reduc- 
tions of  its  Normal  Day,  and  revolutionary  improvements 
with  regard  to  the  Sanitation  and  Safety  of  its  workplaces 
— all  without  injury  to  the  extent  and  regularity  of  its 
members'  employment — may  presently  find  that,  in  spite  of 
its  perfected  organisation  and  accumulated  funds,  its  upward 
course  slackens,  its  movements  for  further  advances  become 
less  frequent  or  less  successful,  and,  in  comparison  with  the 
contemporary  gains  of  other  industries,  the  conditions  of 
employment  will  remain  almost  stationary. 

The  Trade  Unionist  has  a  rough  and  ready  barometer  to 
guide  him  in  this  difficult  navigation.  It  is  impossible,  even 
for  the  most  learned  economist  or  the  most  accomplished 
business  man,  to  predict  what  will  be  the  result  of  any  par- 
ticular advance  in  the  Common  Rule.  So  long,  however,  as 
a  Trade  Union,  without  in  any  way  restricting  the  numbers 
entering  its  occupation,  finds  that  its  members  are  fully 
employed,  it  can  scarcely  be  wrong  in  maintaining  its 
Common  Rules  at  their  existing  level,  and  even,  after  a 
reasonable  interval,  in  attempting  gradually  to  raise  them.1 

When  the  percentage  of  workmen  out  of  employment 
begins  to  rise,  it  is  a  sign  that  the  demand  for  their  particular 
commodity  has  begun  to  slacken.  This  diminution  of  de- 
mand may,  as  we  shall  presently  see,  be  due  to  any  one  of 
an  almost  infinite  number  of  causes,  quite  unconnected  with 
the  conditions  enjoyed  by  the  operatives.  But  one  of  these 

1  This  assumes,  as  is  nearly  always  the  case,  that  the  wages  and  other  condi- 
tions of  employment  are  within  the  limits  of  the  fullest  physiological  efficiency. 
So  long  as  the  family  income  of  the  typical  skilled  mechanic,  even  in  England, 
is  less  than  £100  a  year,  and  his  hours  of  labor  are  more  than  forty  or  fifty  per 
week,  the  potentiality  of  improvement  in  physical  and  mental  efficiency,  in  family 
life  and  citizenship,  no  less  than  in  industry,  is  great. 


Economic  Characteristics  739 

possible  causes  is  a  rise  in  price,  and  one  of  the  possible 
factors  in  a  rise  in  price  is  an  advance  of  the  Common 
Rule  which  does  not  bring  with  it,  in  one  form  or 
another,  a  corresponding  increase  in  the  efficiency  of  the 
industry.  Hence,  although  it  can  in  no  way  be  inferred 
that  the  slackening  of  demand  has  been  caused  by  the  rise 
in  the  level  of  the  Common  Rule,  rather  than  to  any  other 
of  the  many  possible  causes,  yet  this  slackening,  however  it 
is  caused,  must  necessarily  check  any  further  advance.  For 
assuming  the  workmen  to  rely  exclusively  on  the  Device  of 
the  Common  Rule,  it  will  not  pay  them  to  obtain  a  rise  of 
wages,  a  shortening  of  hours,  or  improved  conditions  of  sani- 
tation or  safety  at  the  cost  of  diminishing  their  own  con- 
tinuity of  employment.  To  put  it  concretely,  whenever  the 
percentage  of  the  unemployed  in  a  particular  industry  begins 
to  rise  from  the  3  or  5  per  cent  characteristic  of  "  good 
trade,"  to  the  10,  15,  or  even  25  per  cent  experienced 
in  "  bad  trade,"  there  must  be  a  pause  in  the  operatives' 
advance  movement.1 

1  The  critical  reader  may  retort  that,  when  demand  is  expanding,  a  rise  in  the 
Common  Rule  unaccompanied  by  an  increase  in  efficiency,  may  check  the  expan- 
sion without  actually  throwing  any  men  out  of  work.  This  might  conceivably  be 
the  case,  if  the  particular  rise  in  the  Common  Rule,  which  outstripped  the  increase 
in  efficiency,  took  place  before  the  increased  orders  for  the  commodity  were  given, 
and  if  the  consequent  rise  in  price  merely  choked  off  some  or  all  of  a  coming 
increase  in  demand.  This,  however,  is  not  the  actual  sequence  of  events.  What 
happens  first  is  that  the  increase  in  the  demand  shows  itself  in  the  receipt  of 
unusually  large  orders  by  the  manufacturers.  The  existing  workmen  are  required 
to  work  full  time,  and  then  overtime  ;  most  of  the  unemployed  in  the  trade  get 
taken  on ;  boys  and  other  learners  are  promoted  and  additional  men  are 
inquired  for  ;  old  establishments  are  enlarged,  and  new  ones  are  opened.  On 
this,  the  Trade  Union  asks  for  a  rise  in  wages  or  a  shortening  of  hours.  If 
this  is  conceded,  and  is  not  followed  by  increased  efficiency,  the  rise  in  cost  of 
production  and  therefore  in  price  can  scarcely  fail  actually  to  cause  some  of  the 
men  in  employment  to  be  discharged.  The  more  completely  organised  is  the 
trade,  the  more  precise  is  the  index  afforded  by  the  percentage  of  members 
"on  donat'.on." 


740  Trade  Union  Theory 


[c]  The  effect  of  the  sectional  application  of  the  Common  Ride 
on  the  distribution  of  industry 

We  have  now  to  consider  the  effect  of  the  Device  of  the 
Common  Rule,  not  on  the  particular  trade  that  practises  it, 
but  on  the  development  of  the  nation's  industry — that  is  to 
say,  upon  the  distribution  of  the  capital,  labor,  and  brain 
power  of  any  community  among  the  different  occupations 
that  are  open  to  it.  In  the  complicated  ebb  and  flow  of 
the  modern  world  of  competitive  industry  the  expansion  or 
contraction  of  a  particular  trade  cannot  be  considered  by 
itself.  The  ordinary  manufacturer  or  operative  sees  clearly 
enough  that  the  growth  or  decay  of  his  own  establishment 
is  intimately  connected  with  the  dwindling  or  expansion 
of  other  establishments  in  the  same  trade.  The  economist 
detects  a  similar  rivalry  between  one  occupation  and 
another,  even  within  the  same  community ;  and  sees  the 
area  of  this  competition  between  distinct  classes  of  workers 
indefinitely  enlarged  by  international  trade.  Without  a  full 
appreciation  of  this  silent  but  perpetual  struggle  between 
separate  occupations,  it  is  impossible  to  form  any  correct 
estimate  of  the  influence  of  any  particular  factor  in  the 
distribution  of  industry. 

We  have,  to  begin  with,  the  competition  between  alterna- 
tive ways  of  manufacturing  the  same  product.  We  need  not 
dwell  on  the  historic  struggles  of  the  handloom  weaver  and 
stocking-frame  knitter  against  the  operatives  working  with 
power ;  nor  recur  to  the  contemporary  competition  between 
handmade  clothing  and  boots,  nails  and  ropes,  and  the 
machine-made  articles.  What  is  more  typical  of  our  own 
time  is  the  rivalry  of  one  machine-process  with  another,  such 
as  the  innumerable  ways  of  producing  steel,  or,  to  take  a 
simpler  instance,  the  competition  in  cotton-spinning  between 
the  self-acting  mule,  worked  by  men  and  boys,  and  the 
perfected  ring-frame,  worked  by  women.  A  new  stage  in 
the  competition  is  seen  in  the  substitution  of  one  material 


Economic  Characteristics  741 

for  another,  as,  for  instance,  iron  for  wood  in  the  making  of 
bedsteads,  and  steel  for  iron  in  railway  construction.  A  step 
farther  brings  us  to  the  invention  of  alternative  ways  of 
fulfilling  the  same  desire,  exemplified  in  the  rivalry  between 
the  railway  and  the  road,  the  horse  and  the  electric  motor. 
Finally,  there  is  a  certain  limited  sense  in  which  the  operatives 
making  entirely  unconnected  commodities  compete  for  cus- 
tom, so  that,  as  it  is  commonly  alleged,  the  seasonal  demand 
for  books  and  pianos  fluctuates  inversely  with  that  for 
cricket-bats  and  bicycles. 

So  far  we  have  considered  the  nation  as  a  self-contained 
community,  and  we  have  regarded  the  customers  as  choosing 
only  between  different  products  of  their  own  country. 
Foreign  trade  brings  in  a  new  complication.  The  English 
producers  of  commodities  for  foreign  markets,  and  those  who 
manufacture,  for  home  consumption,  commodities  that  can 
be  imported  from  abroad,  find  their  industries  expanding  or 
contracting  according  as  the  prices  of  their  products  rise  and 
fall  in  other  countries  as  well  as  at  home.  This  may  be 
clearly  seen  in  the  case  of  English  coal.  The  cargoes  from 
Cardiff  and  the  Tyne  go  all  over  the  world  and  find,  in  many 
foreign  ports,  practically  no  competitors.  But  how  far  inland 
our  coals  will  push  into  each  continent  varies  with  every 
change  of  price.  In  Germany  the  Silesian  and  Westphalian 
mines,  in  Australasia  those  of  New  South  Wales,  and  in 
South  Africa  those  of  the  Cape  and  Natal  already  supply  a 
large  part  of  the  local  demand,  and  the  geographical  limit  at 
which  the  use  of  English  coal  ceases  to  be  cheaper  than  the 
inland  supply  is  seen  in  practice  to  be  as  sensitively  mobile 
as  the  thermometer.  And  if  we  turn  to  the  influence  of  the 
import  trade,  we  may  watch  the  area  of  wheat  growing  in 
Great  Britain  expanding  or  contracting  in  close  corre- 
spondence with  the  oscillations  of  the  world  price  of  wheat. 
So  far  the  success  of  any  class  of  English  producers  in  com- 
peting for  the  world's  custom  would  seem  to  depend  ex- 
clusively on  their  ability  to  undersell  the  foreign  producers 
of  the  same  article.  But  this  is  only  half  the  truth.  The 


742  Trade  Union  Theory 

distinctive  effect  of  international  trade  is  to  bring  into  com- 
petitive rivalry,  without  their  being  conscious  of  the  fact, 
many  other  trades  within  the  particular  country  having  no 
apparent  connection  with  each  other.  This  will  be  obvious 
to  any  one  who  considers  for  a  moment  the  relation  between 
exports  and  imports.  Without  sounding  the  depths  of  the 
orthodox  "  Theory  of  International  Trade  "  or  the  mysteries 
of  the  Foreign  Exchanges,  it  will  not  be  doubted  that  any 
increase  in  our  aggregate  exports  does,  in  practice,  tend  to 
cause  at  any  rate  some  increase  in  our  aggregate  imports.  If 
then,  England  for  any  reason  increases  its  export  trade — if, 
for  instance,  a  fall  in  the  cost  of  production  of  English 
machinery,  coal,  and  textiles  enables  Lancashire  and  Cardiff 
increasingly  to  get  the  better  of  their  foreign  rivals  in  neutral 
markets — some  increase  will  certainly  reveal  itself  in  our 
import  trade,  not  in  machinery,  coal,  and  textiles,  but  in  entirely 
different  articles ;  it  may  be,  in  American  food  stuffs  and 
Australian  wool,  or  it  may  be  in  German  glass  wares  and 
Belgian  iron.  Exactly  which  articles  will  be  sent  to  England  in 
increased  quantities  to  pay  for  the  increased  foreign  purchases 
of  machinery,  textiles,  and  coal,  will  depend  on  the  relative 
cheapness  of  production,  both  at  home  and  abroad,  of  all  the 
commodities  consumed  by  England  that  can  also  be  produced 
abroad.  It  may  be  that  food  stuffs  and  wool,  glass  and  iron, 
can  all  be  produced  abroad  actually  cheaper  than  they  are 
selling  in  England.  But  the  increase  will  tend  to  occur,  not 
in  those  commodities  in  which  the  difference  is  least,  but 
principally  in  those  in  which  the  difference  is  greatest. 
Hence  the  expansion  or  contraction  of  English  production 
in  a  particular  industry  working  for  the  home  demand,  is 
affected,  not  only  by  the  foreign  producers  of  the  same 
commodity  for  the  English  market,  but  also  by  the  expansion 
and  contraction  of  every  English  industry  working  for 
export,  and,  yet  again,  by  the  conditions  existing  in  all  the 
other  English  industries  that  are  subject  to  the  competition 
of  imports  from  abroad.  The  enormous  increase  in  our 
imports  of  food  stuffs,  and  the  consequent  contraction  of 


Economic  Characteristics  743 

English  agriculture,  cannot  therefore  be  dissociated  from  the 
contemporary  increase  in  our  exports  :  it  is  the  Lancashire 
cotton-spinner  and  the  Northumberland  coal  hewer  who  are 
most  seriously  competing  with  the  English  farmer.  Or,  to 
take  another  instance,  if  the  jobbing  home  workers  in  the 
Sheffield  cheap  cutlery  trade  keep  down  the  price  of  their 
product  by  working  long  hours,  without  expensive  sanitary 
precautions,  at  the  starvation  wages  of  cut-throat  competition, 
they  may  gain  by  their  wretchedness  a  miserable  exemption 
from  the  competition  of  French  and  German  blades  in  the 
English  market.  But  the  effect  of  this  exemption  is  to  divert 
the  nation's  imports  into  other  commodities.  The  brothers 
and  cousins  of  the  Sheffield  cutlers,  earning  high  wages  in 
the  Yorkshire  glass  works  and  iron  furnaces,  may  therefore 
find  their  employment  diminished  by  the  persistent  influx  of 
German  glass  and  Belgian  iron,  and  they  will  be  entirely 
unaware  that  the  ebb  and  flow  of  their  own  trades  have  any 
connection,  either  with  the  expansions  and  contractions  of 
the  export  trade  of  Lancashire  on  the  one  hand,  or  with  the 
cheapness  of  production  of  Sheffield  cutlery  on  the  other. 
The  same  argument  applies,  it  is  clear,  the  other  way  round. 
The  shrewd  officials  of  the  Lancashire  Cotton  Operatives, 
working  largely  for  export,  are  as  keenly  aware  as  the 
employers  that  in  promoting  a  new  Factory  Bill,  or  in 
resisting  a  reduction  in  their  Piecework  Lists,  they  must  take 
into  account  the  competition  of  Massachusetts  and  Bombay. 
But  neither  workmen  nor  employers  in  Lancashire  realise 
that  in  this  matter  of  foreign  markets  they  have  to  face  no 
less  dangerous  competitors  at  their  own  doors.  Though  the 
aggregate  volume  of  our  export  trade  is  automatically  kept 
up  to  a  point  that  will  discharge  our  foreign  indebtedness,  it 
does  not  at  all  follow  that  the  export  of  each  commodity  will 
remain  the  same.  England  in  this  respect  is  like  one  great 
shop,  from  which  the  foreigner  will  certainly  buy  some  goods. 
But  how  he  will  distribute  his  purchases  among  our  different 
products  will  depend  on  which  of  them,  relatively  to  all  the 
others,  offers  the  greatest  advantage  compared  with  foreign- 


744  Trade  Union  Theory 

made  articles.  If,  without  any  alteration  of  the  balance 
of  indebtedness,  there  springs  up  a  new  business  able  by 
the  relative  cheapness  or  attractiveness  of  its  product  to 
command  a  foreign  market,  the  exports  of  all  our  other 
commodities  will  tend  to  be  injuriously  affected  by  these  new 
sales.  Thus,  the  development  during  the  last  twenty  years 
of  a  large  export  trade  in  ready-made  clothing  and  hardware 
must  have,  to  some  extent,  tended  to  elbow  out  the  elder 
industries,  perhaps  those  of  cotton  and  wool,  some  of  which 
would,  in  the  absence  of  these  new  competitors,  necessarily 
have  expanded  to  balance  the  increase  in  our  imports  of 
food  stuffs.1  The  Lancashire  mule-spinners  must  therefore 

1  Tliis  assumes  that  there  has  been  no  addition  to  the  capital,  brain  power, 
and  labor  of  the  community.  It  has  sometimes  been  urged  that  the  upgrowth  of 
the  wholesale  clothing  trade  in  East  London  has  been  made  possible  only  by  the 
settlement  of  Jewish  immigrants,  and  that  the  newcomers,  creating  a  new  export 
trade,  cause  an  actual  addition  to  our  imports,  and  thus  neither  diminish  em- 
ployment in  other  home  trades  nor  restrict  any  existing  export  trade.  It  is, 
accordingly,  suggested  that  the  Jewish  immigration  is  not  injurious  to  the  English 
wage-earners,  and  that  it  actually  adds  to  English  commercial  prosperity. 

As  a  matter  of  fact,  neither  the  capital  nor  the  brain  power,  which  have 
created  the  new  export  trade  in  slop  clothing,  have  been  provided  by  the  Jewish 
immigrants,  nor  is  it  by  any  means  entirely  carried  on  by  immigrant  labor.  It 
may  be  that  the  opportunity  for  the  trade  in  its  present  form  arises  from  the 
presence  of  these  and  other  workers  of  a  low  Standard  of  Life  ;  but  the  capital 
and  organising  capacity  have  been  supplied  by  our  own  countrymen  ;  and  must 
therefore  be  taken  to  have  been  diverted  by  this  opportunity,  away  from  other 
industries,  which  find  themselves  thereby  subtly  restricted. 

If,  indeed,  the  immigrants  brought  with  them  their  own  capital  and  brain 
power,  and  created  a  new  industry  exclusively  for  export,  the  result  would  be,  as 
suggested,  an  addition  to  our  imports,  and  there  would  be  no  tendency  to  a 
restriction  of  the  other  export  trades.  But  the  pinch  would  then  be  felt  else- 
where. The  additional  imports  would,  of  course,  not  be  the  articles  actually 
consumed  by  the  immigrants,  and  there  would  be  a  shifting  of  trade,  some  home 
industries  expanding  under  the  additional  demand,  others  dwindling  under  the 
competition  of  the  newly-stimulated  imports.  The  total  trade,  apart  from  the 
immigrants'  own  production  and  consumption,  would  neither  be  increased  nor 
decreased  ;  and  the  total  wealth  of  the  nation,  apart  from  the  immigrants'  own 
possessions  and  savings,  not  affected.  The  chief  importance  of  the  immigration 
would  then  lie  in  its  indirect  effects  on  national  character  and  capacity.  If  the 
immigrants,  like  the  Polish  Jews,  brought  in  a  lower  Standard  of  Life,  the  result 
might  be  (besides  increasing  the  overcrowding  of  the  slums)  a  constant  influence 
for  degradation.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  immigrants,  like  the  Huguenots, 
introduced  a  higher  Standard  of  Life,  their  example  might  produce  a  permanent 
improvement  in  national  character.  There  is  also  the  obscure  question  of  the 
effect  of  the  intermixture  of  races  to  be  considered. 


Economic  Characteristics  745 

realise  that  they  are  competing,  not  only  with  the  women 
ring-spinners  in  Lancashire  itself  and  the  mule-spinners  in 
the  foreign  cotton  mills,  but  also  with  the  English  workers  in 
all  the  trades  that  produce  any  article  whatsoever  for  sale  to 
the  foreigner. 

We  come,  therefore,  to  the  conclusion  that  the  employers 
and  operatives  in  any  particular  industry  ought  to  regard 
themselves  as  in  the  truest  sense  competing  for  business,  no 
less  than  for  the  supply  of  capital,  brains,  and  manual  labor, 
with  practically  every  other  industry  in  the  country,  however 
unconnected  with  their  own  it  may  seem  to  be  ;  and  in  this 
competitive  struggle  the  battle,  it  is  obvious,  will  not  always 
be  to  the  strong,  nor  the  race  to  the  swift.  The  ebb  and 
flow  of  business,  and  hence  the  distribution  of  the  nation's 
industry,  and  the  production  of  one  article  rather  than 
another,  depends  on  many  conditions  quite  unconnected  with 
the  conduct  or  efficiency  of  the  employers  or  the  workmen 
concerned,  or  with  their  remuneration.  A  change  of  taste 
or  fashion,  a  scientific  discovery,  the  upgrowth  of  a  new  class 
of  customers,  a  mere  alteration  in  the  nation's  wealth,  or  in 
its  distribution  between  classes,  a  war  or  a  famine,  or  even  a 
sumptuary  law,  will  make  some  trades  expand  and  others 
dwindle,  quite  independently  ol  any  increase  or  decrease  in 
the  cost  at  which  their  products  are  being  turned  out.  And 
even  if  we  restrict  ourselves  to  the  effect  of  price  in  stimulat- 
ing or  contracting  the  demand  for  a  particular  commodity, 
it  will  be  obvious  that  its  cost  of  production  will  vary  for 
many  reasons  totally  unconnected  with  the  requirements  of 
the  employers  or  the  conditions  of  employment  of  the  work- 
people concerned.  The  varying  abundance  or  scarcity  of 
the  raw  material,  the  ease  and  cost  with  which  it  can  be 
transported,  the  discovery  of  a  new  ingredient,  the  invention 
of  a  new  machine  or  a  new  process,  a  change  in  the  incidence 
of  taxation — all  these,  and  numberless  other  factors  uncon- 
nected with  the  conditions  of  employment  affect  cost  of 
production,  and  therefore  price.  It  is,  of  course,  this  extreme 
complication  of  factors  —  this  almost  infinite  degree  of 


746  Trade  Union  Theory 

Plurality  of  Causes  and  Intermixture  of  Effects — that  makes 
it  impossible  to  prove  or  disprove  the  efficacy  of  Trade 
Unionism  by  any  enumeration  of  instances.  What  we  have 
to  do  is,  assuming  each  trade  to  be  incessantly  subjected  to 
the  keenest  competition  of  every  other  trade  at  home  and 
abroad,  to  leave  on  one  side  all  the  other  influences  at  work 
and  examine  what  effect  the  device  of  the  Common  Rule 
itself  exercises  upon  the  distribution  of  industry. 

We  have  seen,  in  our  analysis  of  the  economic  effects  of 
the  Common  Rule  on  the  industries  in  which  it  is  applied, 
that  this  regulation,  with  its  gradual  advance  of  level,  posi- 
tively tends  to  diminish  the  cost  of  production  in  those 
industries.  It  follows  that,  other  things  being  equal,  they 
will  expand  at  a  greater  rate  than  the  unregulated  trades. 
But  it  is  characteristic  of  the  expansion  thus  caused  that  it 
brings  incidental  advantages  to  the  whole  industrial  com- 
munity. The  fact  that  the  labor  and  capital  employed  in 
one  or  more  of  the  nation's  industries  has  become  more 
productive  than  before  does  not  diminish  the  aggregate 
demand  or  the  aggregate  purchasing  power  :  on  the  contrary, 
it  increases  it.  Any  shrinkage  in  particular  trades,  due  to 
the  partial  suppression  of  their  products  by  the  improving 
industries,  will  be  balanced  by  at  least  as  much  expansion 
elsewhere,  due  to  the  increased  purchases  of  these  industries 
themselves.  Moreover,  the  increased  incentive  to  the  invention 
and  perfecting  of  labor-saving  machinery,  the  added  stimulus 
to  the  discovery  of  new  markets,  new  materials,  and  new 
ways  of  satisfying  existing  desires,  which,  as  we  have  seen, 
is  an  inevitable  reaction  from  the  bulwark  of  the  Common 
Rule,  provides  the  unregulated  trades  with  a  stream  of  ready- 
made  appliances,  tested  inventions,  and  new  opportunities, 
which  would  never  have  revealed  themselves  to  their  own 
unstimulated  brains.  Similarly,  the  general  raising  of  the 
Standard  of  Life  of  any  section  of  wage-earners  improves 
the  national  stock,  from  which  all  occupations  draw  their 
recruits.1 

1  Thus,  the  great  English  factory  industry  of  boot  and  shoe  manufacture,  only 


Economic  Characteristics  747 

But  though  the  regulated  industries,  by  progressively 
raising  the  standard  of  mechanical  ingenuity,  organising 
capacity,  and  physical  strength,  will  have  added  to  the  national 
capital  in  all  its  forms,  their  very  superiority  makes  continu- 
ously harder  the  struggle  of  the  unregulated  trades  to  main- 
tain their  position  in  the  world's  market.  The  rapid  adoption 
of  new  inventions  almost  inevitably  involves  the  decay  and 
destruction  of  other  trades.  Thus,  the  enormous  extension 
of  the  use  of  iron  bedsteads — the  product  of  a  highly- 
organised  trade — cannot  fail  to  have  contracted  the  manu- 
facture of  cheap  wooden  bedsteads  in  the  sweating  dens  of 
the  East  End  "  garret  masters."  This  is  obvious  enough 
when  we  consider  the  substitution  of  a  new  commodity  for 
the  inferior  article  which  formerly  satisfied  the  same  want,  or 
even  the  satisfaction  of  one  need  rather  than  another,  as  in 
the  competition  between  books  and  bicycles.  International 
trade,  as  we  have  seen,  causes  the  same  rivalry  to  exist 
between  industries  apparently  unconnected  with  each  other. 
Thus,  the  lowering  of  the  cost  of  production  of  iron  bedsteads 
does  not  interfere  merely  with  the  English  production  of 
wooden  bedsteads  :  by  its  stimulus  to  the  export  of  iron 
bedsteads  it  positively  increases  the  imports  into  England  of 
entirely  different  articles,  and  may,  therefore,  itself  be  one  of 
the  factors  in  the  contraction  of  English  agriculture,  and  of 
the  manufacture  of  the  cheaper  sorts  of  glass,  cutlery,  and 
wood  work. 

recently  emerging  from  the  quagmire  of  Home  Work,  and  itself  as  yet  producing 
hardly  any  inventions,  has  been  made  possible  by  the  amazing  mental  fertility 
of  Connecticut  and  Massachusetts,  where  the  well -organised  workmen  exact 
wages  twice  as  high  as  their  English  rivals.  Similarly,  the  Indian  cotton-mills 
have,  without  effort  of  their  own,  automatically  received  the  inventions  which, 
if  we  may  believe  Babbage  and  the  Edinburgh  Review,  owe  their  very 
existence  to  the  aggressive  Trade  Unionism  of  the  Lancashire  operatives. 
And  the  able  Englishmen  who  began  life  as  artisans,  and  are  now  to  be  found 
in  responsible  positions  in  so  many  continental  factories,  are  plainly  the  result 
of  the  comparatively  high  wages  and  short  hours — not  to  speak  of  the  training 
in  administration — which  the  English  workmen  in  the  regulated  trades  have 
derived  from  their  Trade  Unionism.  In  these  and  many  other  ways  those 
countries  and  those  industries  in  which  a  relatively  high  standard  of  life  is 
enforced,  are  perpetually  dispensing  to  the  world,  out  of  their  abundance,  what 
their  unregulated  rivals  are  unable  to  produce  for  themselves. 


748  Trade  Union  Theory 

More  important  in  its  detrimental  effect  on  the  unregu- 
lated trades  will  be  the  diversion  away  from  them  of  the 
best  industrial  recruits.  In  industries  unregulated  by 
Common  Rules  it  may  suit  the  immediate  profit  and  loss 
account  of  an  employer  to  select,  as  his  foreman,  not  the 
man  who  can  most  improve  the  product  or  the  process,  but 
the  man  who  has  the  greatest  capacity  for  nibbling  at  wages 
or  cribbing  time.  The  fact  that  the  Common  Rules  prevent 
the  beating  down  of  wages,  the  lengthening  of  hours,  or  the 
neglect  of  precautions  against  accidents  or  disease,  automatic- 
ally causes  the  selection,  for  the  post  of  foreman  or  manager, 
of  men  who  have  at  their  command,  in  the  improvement  of 
machinery  and  organisation,  far  more  permanent  and  cumu- 
lative ways  of  reducing  the  cost  of  production  than  taking 
advantage  of  the  operatives'  weakness.  The  concentration 
of  business  in  large  establishments,  which,  as  we  have  seen, 
is  one  of  the  results  of  the  Common  Rule,  directly  encourages 
the  enlistment  in  the  industry  of  men  of  specialised  know- 
ledge and  scientific  attainments.  There  is  an  enormous 
difference,  not  as  yet  adequately  realised,  between  the  sort 
of  man  who  becomes  the  typical  "  small  master "  of  the 
unregulated  trades,  and  the  hierarchy  of  highly -trained 
organisers,  managers,  buyers,  travellers,  agents,  chemists, 
engineers,  metallurgists,  electricians,  designers,  and  inventors 
who  direct  the  business  of  great  establishments.  This  differ- 
ence in  the  quality  of  the  recruiting  is  no  less  marked 
among  the  manual  laborers.  No  operative  who  is  strong 
enough,  or  intelligent  enough,  or  regular  enough  to  get  into 
a  trade  enjoying  high  wages,  short  hours,  and  decent  con- 
ditions of  work  will  stay  in  an  occupation  affording  him 
inferior  advantages.  The  high  standard  enjoyed  by  the 
Lancashire  cotton-spinners  and  engineers,  or  by  the  North- 
umberland miners,  causes  these  trades  to  draw  to  themselves 
the  pick  of  the  young  men  in  their  respective  districts. 
Hence  the  final  curse  of  the  unregulated  trades — they  are 
perpetually  condemned  to  put  up  with  the  inferior  labor 
that  cannot  get  employment  elsewhere.  Every  rise  in  the 


Economic  Characteristics  749 

conditions  of  life  of  the  factory  operative  and  the  coalminer 
makes  it  harder  for  the  country  district  to  retain  the  best 
boys  of  the  village.  Every  time  the  Board  of  Trade  shortens 
the  hours  or  protects  the  lives  of  the  railway  servant ;  each 
new  statute  that  increases  the  certainty  and  amount  of  his 
compensation  for  accident ;  every  rise  in  the  Standard  Rate 
that  public  opinion  secures  to  him,  indirectly  makes  the 
struggle  for  existence  harder  for  the  farmer  and  the  "  little 
master  "  in  the  country  town. 


(d)  Parasitic  Trades 

We  have  hitherto  proceeded  on  the  assumption  that  the 
competition  between  trades  is  unaffected  by  anything  in  the 
nature  of  a  subsidy  or  bounty.  If  the  community  chooses  to 
give  to  all  the  employers  in  a  particular  industry  an  annual 
bounty  out  of  the  taxes,  or  if  it  grants  to  all  the  operatives 
in  that  industry  a  weekly  subsidy  from  the  Poor  Rate  in  aid 
of  their  wages,  it  is  obvious  that  this  special  privilege  will, 
other  things  being  equal,  cause  the  favored  industry  to  out- 
strip its  rivals.  The  subsidy  or  bounty  will  enable  the  en- 
dowed manufacturers  to  bribe  the  public  to  consume  their, 
article,  by  ceding  to  them  what  they  have  not  paid  for. 
An  analogous  advantage  can  be  gained  by  the  employers 
in  a  particular  trade  if  they  are  able  to  obtain  the  use  of 
labor  not  included  in  their  wage-bill.  Under  the  competitive 
pressure  described  in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Higgling  of  the 
Market"  some  of  the  unregulated  trades  become,  in  fact, 
parasitic.  This  occurs,  in  practice,  in  two  distinct  ways. 

We  have  first  the  case  of  labor  partially  subsisted  from 
the  incomes  of  persons  unconnected  with  the  industry  in 
question.  When  an  employer,  without  imparting  any 
adequate  instruction  in  a  skilled  craft,  gets  his  work  done  by 
boys  or  girls  who  live  with  their  parents  and  work  practically 
for  pocket-money,  he  is  clearly  receiving  a  subsidy  or  bounty 
which  gives  his  process  an  economic  advantage  over  those 


75O  Trade  Union  Theory 

worked  by  fully-paid  labor.  But  this  is  not  all.  Even  if 
he  pays  the  boys  or  girls  a  wage  sufficient  to  cover  the  cost 
of  their  food,  clothing,  and  lodging  so  long  as  they  are  in 
their  teens,  and  dismisses  them  as  soon  as  they  become 
adults,  he  is  in  the  same  case.  For  the  cost  of  boys  and 
girls  to  the  community  includes  not  only  their  daily  bread 
between  thirteen  and  twenty-one,  but  also  their  nurture  from 
birth  to  the  age  of  beginning  work,  and  their  maintenance  as 
adult  citizens  and  parents.1  If  a  trade  is  carried  on  entirely 
by  the  labor  of  boys  and  girls  and  is  supplied  with  successive 
relays  who  are  dismissed  as  soon  as  they  become  adults,  the 
mere  fact  that  the  employers  pay  what  seems  a  good  subsist- 
ence wage  to  the  young  people  does  not  prevent  the  trade 
from  being  economically  parasitic.  The  employer  of  adult 
women  is  in  the  same  case  where,  as  is  usual,  he  pays  them 
a  wage  insufficient  to  keep  them  in  full  efficiency,  irrespective 
of  what  they  receive  from  their  parents,  husbands,  or  lovers.2 
In  all  these  instances  the  efficiency  of  the  services  rendered 
by  the  young  persons  or  women  is  being  kept  up  out  of  the 
earnings  of  some  other  class.  These  trades  are  therefore  as 
clearly  receiving  a  subsidy  as  if  the  workers  in  them  were 
being  given  a  "  rate  in  aid  of  wages."  The  English  farmer 
pays,  it  is  true,  no  higher  wages,  but  then  he  receives  in 
return,  since  the  abolition  of  the  Old  Poor  Law,  only  what 
he  pays  for :  his  low  Standard  of  Life  involves  a  low  Stand- 
ard of  Work.  The  employer  of  partially  subsidised  woman 
or  child  labor  gains,  on  the  other  hand,  actually  a  double 
advantage  over  the  self-supporting  trades  :  he  gets  without 
cost  to  himself  the  extra  energy  due  to  the  extra  food,  and 
he  abstracts — possibly  from  the  workers  at  a  rival  process, 

1  To  this,  in  strictness,  should  be  added  their  maintenance  in  old  age  and 
their  burial.     But  only  a  small  proportion   of  the   aged   wage-earners    in  the 
United  Kingdom  are  maintained,  and  eventually  buried,  out  of  their  own  savings 
or  the  assistance  of  relations.     Old  age  and  burial,  like  education,  have  already 
become  to  a  great  extent,  in  the  form  of  charity  or  the  Poor  Law,  charges  upon 
the  community  as  a  whole.     See  Pauperism  aitd  the  Endowment  of  Old  Age 
(London,  1892),  and  The  Aged  Poor  (London,  1894),  by  Charles  Booth. 

2  *'  Women  as  a  rule  are    supplementary    wage-earners." — Charles    Booth, 
Life  and  Labour  of  the  People,  vol.  ix.  p.  205 


Economic  Characteristics  751 

or   in    a   competing   industry — some   of  the   income   which 
might  have  increased  the  energy  put  into  the  other  trade. 

But  there  is  a  far  more  vicious  form  of  parasitism  than 
this  partial  maintenance  by  another  class.  The  continued 
efficiency  of  a  nation's  industry  obviously  depends  on  the 
continuance  of  its  citizens  in  health  and  strength.  For  an 
industry  to  be  economically  self-supporting,  it  must,  therefore, 
maintain  its  full  establishment  of  workers,  unimpaired  in 
numbers  and  vigor,  with  a  sufficient  number  of  children  to 
fill  all  vacancies  caused  by  death  or  superannuation.  If 
the  employers  in  a  particular  trade  are  able  to  take  such 
advantage  of  the  necessities  of  their  workpeople  as  to  hire 
them  for  wages  actually  insufficient  to  provide  enough  food, 
clothing,  and  shelter  to  maintain  them  in  average  health  ; 
if  they  are  able  to  work  them  for  hours  so  long  as  to  deprive 
them  of  adequate  rest  and  recreation  ;  or  if  they  can  subject 
them  to  conditions  so  dangerous  or  insanitary  as  positively 
to  shorten  their  lives,  that  trade  is  clearly  obtaining  a  supply 
of  labor-force  which  it  does  not  pay  for.  If  the  workers 
thus  used  up  were  horses — as,  for  instance,  on  an  urban 
tramway — the  employers  would  have  to  provide,  in  addition 
to  the  daily  modicum  of  food,  shelter,  and  rest,  the  whole 
cost  of  breeding  and  training,  the  successive  relays  necessary 
to  keep  up  their  establishments.  In  the  case  of  free  human 
beings,  who  are  not  purchased  by  the  employer,  this  capital 
value  of  the  new  generation  of  workers  is  placed  gratuitously 
at  his  disposal,  on  payment  merely  of  subsistence  from  day 
to  day.  Such  parasitic  trades  are  not  drawing  any  money 
subsidy  from  the  incomes  of  other  classes.  But  in  thus 
deteriorating  the  physique,  intelligence,  and  character  of 
their  operatives,  they  are  drawing  on  the  capital  stock  of  the 
nation.1  And  even  if  the  using  up  is  not  actually  so  rapid 

1  The  economic  position  of  the  slave-owner  where,  as  latterly  in  the  United 
States  and  Brazil,  the  slaves  had  to  be  bred  for  the  labor  market,  closely  resembles 
that  of  the  tramway  company  using  horse-power.  So  long  as  the  African  slave- 
trade  lasted,  the  importation  of  slaves  being  presumably  cheaper  than  breeding 
them,  the  industries  run  by  slave  labor  were  economically  in  much  the  same 
position  as  our  own  sweated  trades — that  is  to  say,  supplied  with  successive  relays 


752  Trade  Union  Theory 

as  to  prevent  the  "  sweated  "  workers  from  producing  a  new 
generation  to  replace  them,  the  trade  is  none  the  less 
parasitic.  In  persistently  deteriorating  the  stock  it  employs, 
it  is  subtly  draining  away  the  vital  energy  of  the  community. 
It  is  taking  from  these  workers,  week  by  week,  more  than 
its  wages  can  restore  to  them.  A  whole  community  might 
conceivably  thus  become  parasitic  on  itself,  or,  rather,  upon 
its  future.  If  we  imagine  all  the  employers  in  all  the 
industries  of  the  kingdom  to  be,  in  this  sense,  "  sweating " 
their  labor,  the  entire  nation  would,  generation  by  generation, 
steadily  degrade  in  character  and  industrial  efficiency.1  And 
in  human  society,  as  in  the  animal  world,  the  lower  type  de- 
veloped by  parasitism,  characterised  as  it  is  by  the  possession 
of  smaller  faculties  and  fewer  desires,  does  not  necessarily 
tend  to  be  eliminated  by  free  competition.2  The  degenerate 
forms  may,  on  the  contrary,  flourish  in  their  degradation, 
and  depart  farther  and  farther  from  the  higher  type. 
Evolution,  in  a  word,  if  unchecked  by  man's  selective  power, 


of  cheap  but  rapidly  deteriorating  labor — and  the  cheapness  of  their  product, 
observed  Mill,  "  is  partly  an  artificial  cheapness,  which  may  be  compared  to  that 
produced  by  a  bounty  on  production  or  on  exportation  ;  or  considering  the  means 
by  which  it  is  obtained,  an  apter  comparison  would  be  with  the  cheapness  of 
stolen  goods." — Principles  of  Political  Economy ',  Book  III.  ch.  xxv.  §  3,  p.  413 
of  1865  edition. 

1  The  practical  agriculturist  may  see  an  analogy  in  the  case  of  land.      To  the 
theoretic  economist  land  often  appears  as  an  indestructible  instrument  of  production, 
but  the  agricultural  expert  knows  better.      If  under  complete  industrial  freedom 
the  hirers  of  land  sought  only  to  obtain  the  maximum  profit  for  themselves,  it 
would  pay  them  to  extract  for  a  few  years  the  utmost  yield  at  the  minimum  out- 
lay.    The  land  so  treated  would  be  virtually  destroyed  as  an  instrument  of  pro- 
duction, and  could  only  be  brought  into  cultivation  again  by  a  heavy  outlay  of 
capital.      But  this  would  not  matter  to  the  hirer,  if  he  was  free  to  discard  the 
worn-out  farm  when  he  chose,  and  to  take  a  fresh  one.     The  remedy  in  this  case 
is  found  in  the  covenants  by  which  the  owner  of  the  land  regulates  the  use  of  it 
by  the  hirer,  so  as  to  ensure  that  it  shall  be  maintained  in  complete  efficiency. 

2  The  apostles  of  laisser  faire  were  sometimes  startling  in  the  extent  to  which 
they  carried  their  optimism.     Thus,  when  Harriet  Maitineau  was  driven  by  the 
evidence  collected  by  the  Factory  Commissioners  in  1833  to  admit  that  "  the  case 
of  these  wretched  factory  children  seems  desperate,"  she  goes  on  to  add  "the 
only  hope  seems  to  be  that  the  race  will  die  out  in  two  or  three  generations " 
(Harriet  Martineaifs  Atitobiography,  by  Maria  Weston  Chapman,  vol.  iii.  p.  88). 
But  there  was  no  race  of  factory  children  dependent  for  continuance  on  its  own 
reproduction. 


Economic  Characteristics  753 

may  result  in  Degeneration  as  well  as  in  what  we  choose  to 
call  Progress. 

We  might  have  to  accept  as  inevitable  the  incidental 
evils  of  the  parasitic  trades  if  it  could  be  urged  that  their 
existence  resulted  in  any  positive  addition  to  the  national 
wealth — that  is  to  say,  if  they  utilised  capital  and  found 
employment  for  labor  that  would  otherwise  have  been  idle  ; 
or  if  they  fulfilled  desires  that  must  otherwise  have  remained 
unsatisfied.  But  this  is  not  the  case.  We  have,  to  begin 
with,  the  fact  that  the  mere  existence  of  any  parasitic 
industry  tends  incidentally  to  check  the  expansion  of  the 
self-supporting  trades,  whether  these  are  regulated  or  un- 
regulated. Nor  is  it  only  such  unprogressive  industries  as 
agriculture  that  suffer.  In  cotton-spinning,  the  fact  that 
well-nurtured  and  respectable  young  women  can  be  hired  at 
ten  or  twelve  shillings  a  week  is  tempting  the  millowners  to 
substitute  the  ring-frame  for  the  mule  more  extensively  than 
would  be  profitable  if  the  employers  had  to  pay  a  full  sub- 
sistence wage  for  their  ring-spinners,  or  if  they  could  get  for 
their  ten  or  twelve  shillings  a  week  only  such  irregular  and 
inefficient  workers  as  could  or  would  permanently  live  on 
that  income.  The  fact  that  the  female  ring-spinners  have 
been  brought  up  and  are  partly  supported  by  the  mule- 
spinners  themselves,  or  by  other  well-paid  trades  like  the 
engineers,  is  thus  positively  throwing  more  mule-spinners  out 
of  work  than  would  otherwise  be  the  case.  And  there  is,  as 
we  have  seen,  a  more  subtle  competition.  The  fact  that  the 
wholesale  clothing  contractor  is  allowed  to  deteriorate  and 
use  up  in  his  service  the  unfortunate  relays  of  sweated  out- 
workers who  make  his  slop  clothing,  gives  him  actually  a 
constant  supply  of  vital  energy  which  he  need  not  and  does 
not  replace  by  adequate  wages  and  rest,  and  thus  makes  it 
possible  for  him  to  sell  his  product  cheaper,  and  hence  to 
augment  his  export  trade  more  than  he  could  have  done  if 
his  industry  were  free  from  social  parasitism.  And  every 
expansion  of  this  rival  export  trade  tends,  as  we  have  seen, 
to  elbow  out  other  sales  to  the  foreigner — it  may  well  be, 
VOL.  II  3  C 


754  Trade  Union  Theory 

therefore,  to  restrict  the  export,  and  therefore  the  manufacture, 
of  hardware,  machinery,  or  textiles. 

Nor  can  it  be  imagined  that  there  is  anything  so  peculiar 
in  the  nature  of  the  products  of  the  "  sweated  trades,"  that 
they  could  not  be  just  as  efficiently  supplied  to  us  without 
their  evil  parasitism.  We  venture  to  assert,  on  the  contrary, 
that  there  is  no  article  produced  in  the  whole  range  of  the 
parasitic  trades  which  could  not  be  manufactured  with  greater 
technical  efficiency,  and  with  positively  less  labor,  by  a 
highly  regulated  factory  industry.  But  just  as  in  a  single 
trade  the  unregulated  employer  who  can  get  "  cheap  labor " 
is  not  eager  to  put  in  machinery,  so  in  the  nation,  the  enter- 
prising capitalists  who  exploit  some  new  material  or  cater  for 
some  new  desire  inevitably  take  the  line  of  least  resistance. 
If  they  can  get  the  work  done  by  parasitic  labor^  they  will 
have  so  much  the  less  inducement  to  devise  means  of  per- 
forming the  same  service  with  the  aid  of  machinery  and  steam 
power,  and  so  much  the  less  interest  in  adopting  mechanical 
inventions  that  are  already  open  to  them.1  Thus  the  parasitic 
trades  not  only  abstract  part  of  the  earnings  of  other  wage- 
earners,  and  use  up  the  capital  stock  of  national  vigor: 
they  actually  stand  in  the  way  of  the  most  advantageous 
distribution  of  the  nation's  industry,  and  thus  prevent  its 

1  Professor  Schmoller  observes  that  "Self-interest  in  industrial  society  is  like 
steam  in  the  steam-engine :  only  when  we  know  under  what  pressure  it  is  working 
can  we  tell  what  it  will  accomplish"  (Sendschreiben  an  Herrn  von  Treitscke^ 
Berlin,  1875,  P-  37)-  This  is  strikingly  illustrated  by  the  evil  persistence  in 
England,  owing  to  the  absence  of  the  pressure  of  a  Standard  Rate  in  the  sweated 
trades,  of  obsolete  and  uneconomical  processes.  *'  Public  attention  was  directed 
with  some  force  a  short  time  ago  to  the  wretched  condition  of  the  '  nailers '  in 
the  Dudley  district.  In  America  labor  conditions  of  this  kind  are  impossible 
owing  to  the  economic  circumstances  existing,  yet  nails  are  made  at  a  labor  cost 
far  lower  than  that  common  in  the  Dudley  district.  The  output  of  a  worker  in 
an  American  nail  mill  amounts  to  over  2^  tons  per  week,  while  the  Staffordshire 
nailer,  working  on  his  old  method,  only  produces  2  cwt.  Of  what  avail  is  it  that 
the  workman  in  the  latter  case  earn  155.  only,  and  in  the  former  £6  per  week? 
The  labor  cost  per  Ib.  is  in  the  one  case  o.8d.  and  in  the  other  o.25;d.  Thus 
the  earnings  are  eight-fold  greater  in  the  case  of  the  American  workman,  while 
the  labor  cost  is  only  one-third  that  of  the  nail  produced  by  the  English  workman. 
This  is  ...  only  illustrative  of  a  principle  which  runs  through  all  industries. "- 
Manchester  Association  of  Engineers,  Inaugural  Address  by  the  President,  Mr. 
Joseph  Nasmith  (Manchester,  1897),  p.  6. 


Economic  Characteristics  755 

capital,  brains,  and  manual  labor  from  being,  in  the  aggre- 
gate, as  productive  as  they  would  otherwise  be.  So  long  as 
we  assume  each  industry  to  be  economically  self-supporting, 
the  competition  between  trades  may  be  regarded  as  tending 
constantly  to  the  most  productive  distribution  of  the  capital, 
brains,  and  manual  labor  of  the  community.  Each  trade 
would  tend  to  expand  in  proportion  as  it  became  more 
efficient  in  satisfying  the  public  desires,  and  would  be  limited 
only  at  the  point  at  which  some  other  trade  surpassed  it  in 
this  respect.  Every  unit  of  the  nation's  capital,  like  every 
one  of  its  capable  entrepreneurs  and  laborers,  would  tend 
constantly  to  be  attracted  to  the  industry  in  which  they 
would  produce  the  greatest  additional  product.  If,  however, 
some  trades  receive  a  subsidy  or  bounty,  these  parasites  will 
expand  out  of  proportion  to  their  real  efficiency,  and  will  thus 
obtain  the  use  of  a  larger  share  of  the  nation's  capital,  brains, 
and  manual  labor  than  would  otherwise  be  the  case,  with  the 
result  that  the  aggregate  product  will  be  diminished,  and  the 
expansion  of  the  self-supporting  trades  will  be  prematurely 
checked.  This  tendency  of  industry  to  be  forced  by  the 
pressure  for  cheapness,  not  into  the  best,  but  into  the  lowest 
channel,  was  noticed  by  the  shrewd  observers  who  exposed 
the  evils  of  the  old  Poor  Law.  "  Whole  branches  of  manu- 
facture," they  said,  "  may  thus  follow  the  course,  not  of  coal 
mines  or  streams,  but  of  pauperism  ;  may  flourish  like  the 
fungi  that  spring  from  corruption,  in  consequence  of  the 
abuses  which  are  ruining  all  the  other  interests  of  the  place 
in  which  they  are  established,  and  cease  to  exist  in  the 
better  administered  districts,  in  consequence  of  that  better 
administration."  l 

1  First  Report  of  Poor  Law  Commissioners,  1834,  p.  65,  or  reprint  of  1884 
(H.  C.  347  of  1884).  The  disastrous  effects  on  agricultural  labor  of  the  "rate  in  aid 
of  wages  "  of  the  old  Poor  Law  have  become  an  economic  commonplace.  It  seems 
to  be  overlooked  that  what  is  virtually  the  same  bounty  system  prevails  wherever 
work  is  given  out  to  be  done  at  home.  The  scanty  earnings  of  women  outworkers, 
with  their  intermittent  periods  of  unemployment,  inevitably  lead  to  their  being 
assisted  by  private  charity,  if  not  also  from  public  funds.  Thus,  a  recent  investi- 
gator in  Glasgow  reports  that  "  the  returns  of  the  Inspectors  of  the  Poor  show 
that  many  outworkers,  who  are  in  receipt  of  wages  too  small  to  support  them, 


756  Trade  Union  Theory 

This  condition  of  parasitism  is  neither  produced  by  the 
self-helping  efforts  of  the  more  fortunate  trades  to  improve 
their  own  conditions,  nor  can  it  be  remedied  by  any  such 
sectional  action.  The  inadequate  wages,  excessive  hours, 
and  insanitary  conditions  which  degrade  and  destroy  the 
victims  of  the  sweated  trades  are  caused  primarily  by  their 
own  strategic  weakness  in  face  of  the  employer,  himself 
driven  to  take  advantage  of  their  necessities  by  the  uncon- 
scious pressure  described  in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Higgling  of 
the  Market."  That  weakness,  and  the  industrial  inefficiency 
to  which  it  inevitably  leads,  are  neither  caused  nor  increased 
by  the  fact  that  other  sections  of  wage -earners  earn  high 
wages,  work  short  hours,  or  enjoy  healthy  conditions  of 
employment.  If,  as  we  have  argued,  these  conditions, 
enforced  by  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule,  themselves 
produce  the  high  degree  of  specialised  efficiency  which 
enables  them  to  be  provided,  their  existence  is  no  dis- 
advantage to  the  community,  nor  to  any  section  of  it.  On 
the  contrary,  the  resulting  expansion  of  the  regulated  trades 
will  have  reclaimed  an  additional  area  from  the  morass.  If, 
on  the  other  hand,  they  are  not  accompanied  by  a  full 
equivalent  of  efficiency,  their  existence  in  the  regulated 
industries,  by  increasing  cost  of  production,  must  be  a  draw- 
back to  these  in  the  competition  between  trades,  and  thus 
positively  lessen  the  pressure  on  the  unregulated  occupations 
and  the  workers  in  them.2  On  neither  view  can  the  relatively 

though  working  full  time,  are  aided  from  the  rates.  Moreover,  although  to  an 
extent  which  it  is  impossible  to  ascertain,  many  of  the  outworkers  on  low  wages 
are  assisted  by  the  churches  and  by  charities.  Here  evidently  part  of  the  wages 
is  paid  by  outsiders.  .  .  .  The  cheapness  of  goods  made  in  such  circumstances 
is  balanced  by  the  increase  in  Poor  Rates  and  in  the  demands  on  the  benevolent." 
— Home  Work  amongst  Women,  by  Margaret  H.  Irwin  (Glasgow,  1897). 

2  Thus,  in  the  international  competition  between  trades,  the  maintenance 
of  wages  at  high  rates  by  means  of  Restriction  of  Numbers  is  calculated  to  be 
disastrous  to  the  trade  practising  this  device.  The  high  price  of  the  labor, 
coupled  with  its  declining  efficiency,  can  scarcely  fail  to  cause  an  increase  in  the 
price  of  the  product.  If  this  comes  into  competition  with  foreign  articles,  or  if  a 
cheap  substitute  can  easily  be  found,  the  trade  will  quickly  be  checked  and  the 
falling  off  in  demand,  leading  to  some  workmen  losing  their  employment,  will 
call  for  increased  stringency  in  excluding  fresh  learners.  The  effect  of  the 
Restriction  of  Numbers  in  any  trade,  if  this  is  pushed  so  far  as  seriously  to  raise 


Economic  Characteristics  757 

good  conditions  exacted  by  the  coalminer  or  the  engineer 
be  said  to  be  in  any  way  prejudicial  to  the  chain  and  nail 
maker  of  the  Black  Country  or  the  outworking  Sheffield 
cutler,  to  the  sweated  shirtmaker  of  Manchester  or  the  casual 
dock  laborer  of  an  East  London  slum.  Their  influence,  such 
as  it  is,  is  all  in  the  other  direction.  The  fact  that  a  brother, 
cousin,  or  friend  is  receiving  a  higher  wage,  working  shorter 
hours,  or  enjoying  better  sanitary  conditions  is  an  incentive 
to  struggle  for  similar  advantages.1 

Unfortunately  there  is  no  chance  of  the  parasitic  trades 
raising  themselves  from  their  quagmire  by  any  sectional 
action  of  their  own.  It  is,  for  instance,  hopeless  for  the 
casual  dock  laborers  of  London  to  attempt,  by  Mutual 
Insurance  or  Collective  Bargaining,  to  maintain  any  effective 
Common  Rules  against  the  will  of  their  employers.  Even 
if  every  man  employed  at  dock  labor  in  any  given  week 
were  a  staunch  and  loyal  member  of  the  Trade  Union,  even  if 
the  union  had  funds  enough  to  enable  all  these  men  to  stand 
out  for  better  terms,  they  would  still  be  unable  to  carry 
their  point.  The  employers  could,  without  appreciable  loss, 
fill  their  warehouses  the  very  next  day  by  an  entirely  new 

the  price  of  the  product,  is,  therefore,  actually  to  drive  more  and  more  of  the 
nation's  capital  and  labor  from  the  restricted  industry,  and  its  progressive  dwind- 
ling, even  to  the  point  of  complete  extinction,  or  transfer  to  another  countiy. 

1  It  may  be  said  that  one  class  of  parasitic  workers — women  or  child  workers 
— are  partly  supported  from  the  wages  of  other  operatives,  usually  better  paid  ; 
and  that  their  parasitism  is  thus  made  possible  by  the  existence  of  these  better 
paid  operatives,  and  therefore,  in  some  sense,  by  Trade  Unionism.  There  is, 
however,  no  connection  between  the  two.  This  kind  of  parasitism  does,  indeed, 
imply  a  donor  of  the  bounty  as  well  as  a  recipient,  but  the  existe/ice  of  differences 
in  income  between  individuals,  or  even  between  classes,  is  in  no  way  dependent 
on  Trade  Unionism.  Moreover,  there  are  some  cases — such  as  the  relation 
between  home  work  and  casual  dock  labor  in  East  London — in  which  two 
equally  low-paid  occupations  may  be  said,  by  their  alternate  mutual  help,  to  be 
parasitic  on  each  other.  The  facility  of  obtaining  "large  supplies  of  low-paid 
labor,"  says  Mr.  Charles  Booth,  "may  be  regarded  as  the  proximate  cause  of  the 
expansion  of  some  of  the  most  distinctive  manufacturing  industries  of  East  and 
South  London — furniture,  boots  and  shoes,  caps,  clothing,  paper  bags,  and  card- 
board boxes,  matches,  jam,  etc.  .  .  .  They  are  found  in  the  neighbourhood  of 
districts  largely  occupied  by  unskilled  or  semi-skilled  workmen,  or  by  those  whose 
employment  is  most  discontinuous,  since  it  is  chiefly  the  daughters,  wives,  and 
-widows  of  these  men  who  turn  to  labor  of  this  kind.'''' — C.  Booth:  Life  and  Labour 
of  the  People  (London,  1897),  vol.  ix.  p.  193. 


758  Trade  Union  Theory 

set  of  men,  who  would  do  the  work  practically  as  well. 
There  is,  in  fact,  for  unspecialised  manual  labor  a  practically 
unlimited  "  reserve  army "  made  up  of  the  temporarily 
unemployed  members  of  every  other  class.  As  these 
form  a  perpetually  shifting  body,  and  the  occupation  of 
"  general  laboring  "  needs  no  apprenticeship,  no  combination, 
however  co-extensive  it  might  be  with  the  laborers  actually 
employed  at  any  one  time,  could  deprive  the  employer 
of  the  alternative  of  engaging  an  entirely  new  gang. 
The  same  reason  makes  it  for  ever  hopeless  to  attempt, 
by  Mutual  Insurance  or  Collective  Bargaining,  to  raise 
appreciably  the  wages  of  the  common  run  of  women  workers. 
Where,  as  is  usually  the  case,  female  labor  is  employed  for 
practically  unskilled  work,  needing  only  the  briefest  experi- 
ence ;  or  where  the  work,  though  skilled,  is  of  a  kind  into 
which  every  woman  is  initiated  as  part  of  her  general  educa- 
tion, no  combination  will  ever  be  able  to  enforce,  by  its 
own  power,  any  Standard  Rate,  any  Normal  Day,  or  any 
definite  conditions  of  Sanitation  and  Safety.  This  is  even 
more  obvious  when  the  parasitic  labor  is  that  of  boys 
or  girls,  taken  on  without  any  industrial  experience  at  all. 
Mutual  Insurance  and  Collective  Bargaining,  as  methods  of 
enforcing  the  Common  Rule,  become  impotent  when  the 
work  is  of  so  unskilled  or  so  unspecialised  a  character  that 
an  employer  can,  without  economic  disadvantage,  replace 
his  existing  hands  in  a  body  by  an  entirely  new  set  of 
untrained  persons  of  any  antecedents  whatsoever. 

The  outcome  of  this  analysis  is  that  the  strongest 
competitors  for  the  world's  custom,  and  for  the  use  of  the 
nation's  brains  and  capital,  will  be  the  regulated  industries 
on  the  one  hand,  and  the  parasitic  trades  on  the  other — the 
unregulated  but  self-supporting  industries  having  to  put  up 
with  the  leavings  of  both  home  and  foreign  trade,  and  a 
diminishing  quantity  and  quality  of  organising  capacity  and 
manual  labor.1  In  what  proportion  a  nation's  industry  will 

1  It  may  be  desirable  to  observe,  in  order  to  prevent  possible  misunderstand- 
ing, that  we  propose  this  division  of  industries  into  three  classes,  as  a  Classification 


Economic  Characteristics  759 

be  divided  among  the  two  conquerors  will,  it  is  obvious, 
depend  primarily  on  the  extent  to  which  regulation  is 
resorted  to.  The  more  widespread  and  effective  is  the  use 
of  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule,  the  larger,  other  things 
being  equal,  will  be  the  proportion  of  the  population  pro- 
tected from  the  ravages  of  "  sweating."  On  the  other  hand, 
the  more  generally  the  conditions  of  employment  are  left  to 
be  freely  settled  by  Individual  Bargaining,  the  wider  will 
grow  the  area  of  the  parasitic  trades.  And  omitting  from 
consideration  those  industries  which  are  at  once  unregulated 
and  self-supporting — which  succumb,  as  we  have  seen,  before 
either  victor — it  would  require  delicate  economic  investiga- 
tion to  estimate  the  relative  advantage,  in  this  day-to-day 
struggle  between  industries,  of  the  slow  but  cumulative 
stimulus  given  by  the  Common  Rule,  on  the  one  hand,  and, 
on  the  other,  the  immediate  cheapening  of  production  made 
possible  by  parasitism,  whether  this  takes  the  form  of  grants 
in  aid  of  subsistence  from  persons  outside  the  industry,  or 
of  an  unremunerated  consumption  of  labor's  capital  stock. 
We  might  infer,  from  the  respective  economic  characteristics 

by  Type,  not  by  Definition.  "It  is  determined,  not  by  a  boundary  line  without, 
but  by  a  central  point  within  ;  not  by  what  it  strictly  excludes,  but  by  what  it 
eminently  includes  ;  by  an  example,  not  by  a  precept "  (Whewell,  History  of 
Scientific  Ideas,  vol.  ii.  p.  120;  Mill,  System  of  Logic >  vol.  ii.  p.  276).  Here, 
as  elsewhere  in  Nature,  there  are  no  sharp  lines  of  division.  The  different  trades 
shade  off  from  each  other  by  imperceptible  degrees.  So  far  as  we  are  aware, 
there  is  no  industry  that  is  completely  regulated,  none  that  is  completely  un- 
regulated and  self-supporting,  and  none  that  is  completely  parasitic.  Mule-spinning, 
for  example,  is  a  highly-regulated  industry,  but  in  so  far  as  it  is  fed  with  relays  of 
piecers  whom  it  does  not  support,  it  is  parasitic  on  other  trades.  Agriculture, 
though  mainly  driven  to  be  self-supporting,  is,  in  some  districts,  parasitic  on 
occupations  with  which  it  is  combined,  such  as  fishing  or  letting  lodgings  ;  and 
though  mainly  unregulated,  sometimes  employs  workmen  at  wages  governed  by 
a  Standard  Rate,  or  residing  in  farm  cottages,  as  to  which  there  is  some  attempt 
to  enforce  the  Public  Health  Acts.  The  parasitic  trades  themselves  usually 
employ  a  modicum  of  organised  labor,  and  their  operations  are  frequently 
divided  between  the  highly-regulated  factory  and  the  unregulated  home.  It  is 
accordingly  impossible  to  discover  whether  or  not  an  industry  is  parasitic  by  any 
such  operation  as  dividing  the  total  wages  that  it  pays  among  the  total  number 
of  its  employees.  Any  trade  is  so  far  parasitic  if  it  employs  any  labor  which  is 
not  entirely  maintained  and  replaced  out  of  the  wages  and  other  conditions  afforded 
to  that  particular  labor.  Our  remarks  as  to  parasitic  trades  apply,  therefore,  to  all 
industries  whatsoever,  in  so  far  as  they  are  parasitic. 


760  Trade  Union  Theory 

of  these  two  sources  of  industrial  advantage,  that  the  regu- 
lated trades  would  expand  steadily,  generation  after  genera- 
tion, improving  the  quality  of  their  products  even  more 
rapidly  than  reducing  their  price,  and  thus  tending  to  oust 
their  rivals  principally  in  the  more  complicated  productive 
processes  and  the  finer  grades  of  workmanship.  The 
parasitic  trades,  on  the  contrary,  would  form  a  constantly 
shifting  body,  cropping  up  suddenly  in  new  forms  and 
unexpected  places,  each  in  succession  gaining  a  quick  start 
in  the  world's  market  by  the  cheapness  of  its  product,  often 
realising  great  fortunes,  but  each  gradually  losing  ground 
before  other  competitors,  and  thus  individually  failing  to 
secure  for  itself  a  permanent  place  in  the  nation's  industry. 

Amid  all  the  complications  of  human  society,  it  is  im- 
possible to  give  inductive  proof  of  any  generalisation  whatso- 
ever. But  the  outcome  of  our  analysis  is  certainly  consistent 
with  the  main  developments  of  British  trade  during  the 
nineteenth  century,  and  with  its  present  aspect.  If,  for 
instance,  we  compare  the  distribution  of  industry  in  Great 
Britain  fifty  years  ago  with  that  of  the  present  day,  we  are 
struck  at  once  by  the  enormous  increase  in  the  proportion 
occupied  by  textile  manufactures  (especially  cotton),  ship- 
building, machine -making,  and  coal-mining,1  as  compared 
with  agriculture,  and  with  those  skilled  handicrafts  like 
watchmaking,  silk -weaving,  and  glove -making,  for  which 
England  was  once  celebrated.  To  whatever  causes  we  may 
ascribe  the  success  of  the  former  industries,  it  is  at  least 
a  striking  coincidence  that  they  are  exactly  those  in  which 
the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule,  whether  enforced  by 
Collective  Bargaining  or  Legal  Enactment,  has  been  most 
extensively  and  continuously  applied.  Equally  significant 
is  the  fact  that  the  expansion  of  our  manufactures  is  now 
taking  place,  in  the  main,  less  in  the  lower  grades  of  quality 
than  in  the  higher.  Thus,  it  is  in  the  finer  "  counts "  of 

1  These  four  great  staple  industries  now  contribute  three-quarters  of  the  whole 
exports  of  British  production,  and  an  ever-increasing  proportion  of  our  manufac- 
tures for  home  consumption. 


Economic  Characteristics  761 

yarn,  the  best  longcloth,  and  the  most  elaborately  figured 
muslins — not  in  the  commoner  sorts  of  cotton  goods — that 
Lancashire  exports  find  their  widest  market.  In  ship- 
building, the  highly  complicated  and  perfectly  finished  war- 
ship and  passenger  liner  are  the  most  distinctively  British 
products.  And  English  steam-engines,  tools,  and  machinery 
are  bought  by  the  foreigner  in  yearly  increasing  quantities, 
not  because  they  are  lower -priced  than  many  continental 
manufactures,  but  because  they  more  than  retain  their  pre- 
eminence in  quality.  Coincidently  with  this  expansion  in 
the  most  skilled  parts  of  our  regulated  trades  has  been  the 
gradual  ousting,  even  in  the  home  market,  of  our  manu- 
factures of  the  commoner  sorts  of  joinery,  glass,  paper,  and 
cutlery — all  branches  in  which  the  English  workmen  have 
never  been  sufficiently  organised  to  enforce  a  Standard  Rate 
or  a  Normal  Day.1  We  might  follow  out  this  coincidence 
between  expansion  and  regulation  still  further,  pursuing  it 
across  the  cleavage  of  handwork  versus  machinery,  and  not- 
ing the  success  of  the  highly  organised  Kentish  hand  paper- 
makers  and  Nottingham  machine  laceworkers,  in  comparison 
with  the  relative  weakness  before  foreign  competition  of  the 
machine  papermakers  and  hand  laceworkers,  both  of  which 
have  always  been  practically  unorganised  trades,  earning  low 
wages.  It  is  interesting  to  note  that,  with  the  exception  of 
the  hand  laceworkers,  all  these  weak  or  decaying  industries 
are  carried  on  by  adult  men,  and  therefore  debarred  from 
the  ordinary  form  of  parasitic  subsidy.  But  the  most 
remarkable  decline  of  an  unregulated  and  self-supporting 
industry  is  afforded  by  British  agriculture.  The  fact  that 
the  English  farmer  has  always  been  able  to  hire  his  labor 
at  practically  its  bare  subsistence,  and  that,  unlike  the  mill- 
owner,  he  is  free  to  exact  unlimited  hours  of  work,  and  is 

1  In  these  very  industries  the  more  skilled  branches  of  work,  producing  the 
finer  kinds  of  glass,  cutlery,  paper,  and  furniture,  in  which  the  men  insist  on  high 
standard  conditions,  have  usually  suffered  comparatively  little  from  foreign  inva- 
sion, in  spite  of  the  fact  that  their  old-fashioned  unions  have  retained  the  Device 
of  Restriction  of  Numbers,  and  have  thus,  as  we  believe,  prevented  an  expansion 
of  their  crafts. 


762  Trade  Union  Theory 

untrammelled  by  any  sanitary  requirements,  has,  we  believe, 
had  the  worst  possible  effect  on  agricultural  prosperity.  It 
has,  to  begin  with,  deprived  the  typically  rural  industry  of 
anything  but  the  residuum  of  the  rural  population.  For 
a  whole  century  the  cleverest  and  most  energetic  boys,  the 
strongest  and  most  enterprising  young  men,  have  been 
drained  from  the  countryside  by  the  superior  conditions 
offered  by  the  industries  governed  by  the  Common  Rule.  It 
follows  that  the  employer  has  for  generations  had  very  little 
choice  of  labor,  and  practically  no  chance  of  securing  fresh 
relays  of  workers  from  other  occupations.  Moreover,  though 
he  may  reduce  wages  to  a  bare  subsistence,  he  can,  in  the 
long  run,  get  no  more  out  of  the  laborers  than  his  wages 
provide,  for  it  is  upon  them  and  their  families  that  he  must 
rely  for  a  continuance  of  the  service.  Hence  the  scanty 
food  and  clothing,  long  hours,  and  insanitary  housing  accom- 
modation of  the  rural  population  produce  slow,  lethargic,  and 
unintelligent  labor :  the  low  Standard  of  Life  is,  as  we  have 
mentioned,  accompanied  by  a  low  Standard  of  Work.  What 
is  no  less  important,  the  employers  have,  of  all  classes, 
troubled  least  about  making  inventions  or  improving  their 
processes.  If  a  farmer  .cannot  make  both  ends  meet,  his 
remedy  is  to  get  a  reduction  of  rent.  The  very  fact  that  an 
agricultural  tenant,  unlike  a  mine  owner  or  a  cotton  manu- 
facturer, is  not  held  rigidly  to  his  bargain  with  his  landlord, 
and  is  frequently  excused  a  part  of  his  rent  in  unprofitable 
years,  prevents  that  vigorous  weeding  out  of  the  less  efficient, 
and  that  constant  supersession  of  the  unfit,  which  is  one  of 
the  main  factors  of  the  efficiency  of  Lancashire.  It  is  there- 
fore not  surprising  that,  in  a  century  of  unparalleled  technical 
improvement  in  almost  every  productive  process,  the  methods 
of  agriculture  have,  we  believe,  changed  less  than  those  of 
any  other  occupation.  In  the  rivalry  between  trades  it  has 
steadily  lost  ground,  securing  for  itself  an  ever-dwindling 
proportion  of  the  nation's  capital,  and  losing  constantly  more 
and  more  of  the  pick  of  the  population  that  it  nourishes. 
In  the  stress  of  international  competition  it  has  gone  increas- 


Economic  Characteristics  763 

ingly  to  the  wall,  and  far  from  being  selected,  like  such 
highly  regulated  trades  as  coal  mining  or  engineering,  for  the 
supply  of  the  world  market,  it  finds  itself  losing  more  and 
more  even  of  the  home  trade  ;  not  to  any  specially  favored 
one  among  its  rivals,  but  to  all  of  them  ;  not  alone  in  wheat- 
growing,  but  in  every  other  branch  of  its  operations.  There 
are,  of  course,  other  causes  for  the  decline  of  English  farming, 
and  we  are  far  from  pretending  to  offer  a  complete  explana- 
tion of  its  relatively  backward  condition,  as  compared,  say, 
with  shipbuilding  or  machine -making.  But  the  country 
gentlemen  of  1833-1847,  who  so  willingly  imposed  the 
Factory  Acts  on  the  millowners,  and  so  vehemently  objected 
to  any  analogous  regulations  being  applied  to  agriculture, 
would  possibly  not  have  been  so  eager  to  support  Lord 
Shaftesbury  if  they  had  understood  clearly  the  economic 
effects  of  these  Common  Rules.1 

1  Even  within  a  trade  the  districts  in  which  the  Common  Rule  is  rigidly 
enforced  will  often  outstrip  those  lacking  this  stimulus  to  improvement.  Thus, 
in  cotton-spinning  Glasgow  once  rivalled  Lancashire,  and  for  the  first  third  of  the 
present  century  the  two  districts  did  not  appreciably  differ  in  the  extent  of  their 
regulation.  During  the  last  sixty  years  the  growth  of  Trade  Unionism  in  Lanca- 
shire has  led  to  a  constant  elaboration,  raising,  and  ever  more  stringent  enforce- 
ment of  the  Common  Rules  by  which  the  industry  is  governed.  In  Glasgow,  on 
the  other  hand,  the  operatives'  violence  and  the  employers'  autocratic  behaviour 
led  to  serious  outbreaks  of  crime  between  1830  and  1837,  followed  by  drastic 
repression  and  the  entire  collapse  of  Trade  Unionism  in  the  textile  industry. 
From  1838  down  to  the  present  day  the  Glasgow  cotton  manufacturers  have,  so 
far  as  Trade  Unionism  is  concerned,  been  practically  free  to  hire  their  labor  as 
cheaply  as  they  pleased,  whilst,  owing  to  the  lack  of  organisation,  even  the  Com- 
mon Rules  of  the  Factory  Acts  have,  until  the  last  few  years,  been  far  less  rigidly 
enforced  than  in  Lancashire.  It  is  at  least  an  interesting  coincidence  that  during 
this  period,  whilst  other  manufacturing  industries  have  enormously  progressed, 
Glasgow  cotton-spinning  has  steadily  declined  in  efficiency.  A  lower  grade  of 
labor  is  now  employed,  much  of  it  paid  only  the  barest  subsistence  wage  ;  the 
speed  of  working  and  output  per  operative  have  failed  to  increase  ;  improvements 
in  machinery  have  been  tardily  and  inadequately  adopted  ;  and  no  new  mills  have 
recently  been  erected.  Only  a  few  establishments  now  remain  out  of  what  was 
once  a  flourishing  industry,  and  it  is  doubtful  whether  all  of  these  will  long 
survive. 

Cloth  manufacture  supplies  a  similar  example.  The  cloth  mills  of  the  West 
of  England  have  enjoyed  the  advantage  of  inherited  tradition,  and  a  world-wide 
reputation  for  excellence  of  quality.  Since  the  very  beginning  of  the  century  the 
industry  has  been  entirely  free  from  Trade  Unionism.  Wages  have  been  exceed- 
ingly low,  and  the  Factory  Inspector  has  certainly  never  been  instigated  to  any 
particular  activity.  Water-power  is  abundant  and  coal  cheap,  whilst  canals  and 


764  Trade  Union  Theory 

Unfortunately,  the  triumphant  progress  of  the  regulated 
trades,  as  compared  with  the  unregulated  but  self-supporting 
industries,  does  not  complete  the  picture  of  our  industrial  life. 
In  the  crowded  slums  of  the  great  cities,  in  the  far  out-stretch- 
ing suburbs  and  industrial  villages  which  are  transforming  so 
much  of  Great  Britain  into  cross -cutting  chains  of  houses, 
there  are  constantly  springing  up  all  sorts  and  conditions  of 
mushroom  manufactures — the  innumerable  articles  of  wear- 
ing apparel,  cheap  boots  and  slippers,  walking-sticks  and 
umbrellas,  mineral  waters  and  sweetstuffs,  the  lower  grades 
of  furniture  and  household  requisites,  bags  and  boxes,  toys 
and  knick-knacks  of  every  kind — in  short,  a  thousand  mis- 
cellaneous trades,  none  of  which  can  be  compared  in  per- 
manence or  extent  with  any  one  of  our  staple  industries,  but 
which  in  the  aggregate  absorb  a  considerable  proportion  of 
the  custom,  capital,  and  organising  capacity  of  the  nation. 
This  is  the  special  field  of  the  "  small  master,"  driven  per- 
petually to  buy  his  material  on  credit  and  to  sell  his  product 
to  meet  the  necessities  of  the  hour  ;  of  the  speculative  trader 
commanding  capital  but  untrained  in  the  technological  details 
of  any  mechanical  industry ;  of  armies  of  working  sub- 
contractors, forced  by  the  pressure  of  competition  and  the 
absence  of  regulation  to  grind  the  faces  of  the  poor  ;  and,  on 
the  other  hand,  of  the  millions  of  unorganised  workers,  men, 
women,  and  children,  who,  from  lack  of  opportunity,  lack  of 
strength,  or  lack  of  technical  training,  find  themselves  unable 
to  escape  from  districts  or  trades  in  which  the  absence  of 
regulation  drives  them  to  accept  wages  and  conditions  incon- 
sistent with  industrial  efficiency.  We  are  here  in  a  region 
seemingly  apart  from  the  world  of  the  Great  Industry  to 
which  our  country  owes  its  industrial  predominance.  These 

railways  make  both  Bristol  and  London  accessible.  Yet  the  cloth  manufacturers 
of  Gloucestershire,  Somersetshire,  and  Wiltshire  have  throughout  been  steadily 
losing  ground  before  those  of  Yorkshire  and  Lancashire.  This  decline  was 
expressly  attributed  by  one  of  the  most  enterprising  of  them  to  the  lack  of 
stimulus  to  improvement,  manifest  alike  among  the  foremen  and  the  employers. 
Whether  our  informant  would  have  consciously  welcomed  the  quickening  of 
Functional  Adaptation  and  Selection  of  the  Fittest,  brought  about  by  the  Common 
Rules  of  a  strong  Trade  Union  is,  however,  doubtful  ! 


Economic  Characteristics  765 

'  sweated  trades  "  seldom  enter  into  direct  competition  with 
the  highly -organised  and  self-supporting  staple  industries. 
What  happens  is  that  one  form  of  parasitism  dogs  the  steps 
of  the  other — the  wholesale  trader  or  sub-contractor  using 
up  relays  of  deteriorating  outworkers,  underbids  the  factory- 
owner  resorting  to  the  subsidised  labor  of  respectable  young 
women.  It  is  refreshing  to  notice  that  when  one  of  these 
sweated  trades  does  get  partially  caught  up  into  the  factory 
system,  and  thus  comes  under  Common  Rules  with  regard 
to  Hours  of  Labor  and  Sanitation,  the  factories,  even  when 
they  pay  little  more  than  pocket-money  wages  to  their  women 
operatives,  draw  slowly  ahead  of  their  more  disastrously 
parasitic  rivals.1  But  this  very  competition  of  subsidised 
factory  labor  with  deteriorating  outworkers  makes  things  worse 
for  these  latter.  To  what  depth  of  misery  and  degradation 
the  higgling  of  the  market  may  reduce  the  denizens  of  the 
slums  of  our  great  cities  is  unsounded  by  the  older  econo- 
mists' pedantic  phrase  of  "  subsistence  level."  Unfortunately 
the  harm  that  the  sweater  does  lives  after  him.  Men  and 
women  who  have,  for  any  length  of  time,  been  reduced,  to 
quote  the  House  of  Lords'  Committee,  to  "  earnings  barely 
sufficient  to  sustain  existence  ;  hours  of  labor  such  as  to 
make  the  lives  of  the  workers  periods  of  almost  ceaseless  toil, 
hard  and  unlovely  to  the  last  degree ;  sanitary  conditions 
injurious  to  the  health  of  the  persons  employed  and  dangerous 
to  the  public," 2  become  incapable  of  profitable  labor.  What 
they  can  do  is  to  compete  fitfully  for  the  places  which  they 
cannot  permanently  fill,  and  thus  not  only  drag  down  the 
wages  of  all  other  unregulated  labor,  but  also  contribute, 
by  their  irregularity  of  conduct  and  incapacity  for  persistent 
effort,  to  the  dislocation  of  the  machinery  of  production.  But 
this  is  not  all.  No  one  who  has  not  himself  lived  among 
the  poor  in  London  or  Glasgow,  Liverpool  or  Manchester, 

1  In  the  slop  clothing  trade,  the  factories  at  Leeds  and  elsewhere,  employ- 
ing girls  and  women  at  extremely  low  wages,  but  under  good  sanitary  conditions 
and  fixed  hours,  are  steadily  increasing. 

2  Final  Report  of  the  Select  Committee  of  the  House  of  Lords  on  the  Sweating 
System,  1890, 


766  Trade  Union  Theory 

can  form  any  adequate  idea  of  the  unseen  and  unmeasured 
injury  to  national  character  wrought  by  the  social  contam- 
ination to  which  this  misery  inevitably  leads.  One  degraded 
or  ill-conducted  worker  will  demoralise  a  family  ;  one  dis- 
orderly family  inexplicably  lowers  the  conduct  of  a  whole 
street ;  the  low -caste  life  of  a  single  street  spreads  its  evil 
influence  over  the  entire  quarter ;  and  the  slum  quarter, 
connected  with  the  others  by  a  thousand  unnoticed  threads 
of  human  intercourse,  subtly  deteriorates  the  standard  of 
health,  morality,  and  public  spirit  of  the  whole  city.  Thus 
though  the  morass  does  not  actually  gain  on  the  portion  of 
the  nation's  life  already  embanked  by  the  Common  Rule, 
we  see  it  perpetuating  itself,  and,  with  the  growth  of  popula- 
tion, even  positively  increasing  in  area.1 


(e)   The  National  Minimum 

Though  Trade  Unionism  affords  no  means  of  putting 
down  industrial  parasitism  by  sectional  action,  the  analysis 
of  the  economic  effects  of  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule 
points  the  way  to  the  solution  of  the  problem.  Within  a 
trade,  in  the  absence  of  any  Common  Rule,  competition 
between  firms  leads,  as  we  have  seen,  to  the  adoption  of 
practices  by  which  the  whole  industry  is  deteriorated.  The 

1  Whilst  the  proportion  of  those  who  fall  below  the  level  of  healthy  sub- 
sistence has  no  doubt  greatly  decreased  in  the  sixty  years  1837-1897,  there  is  good 
reason  to  believe  that  their  actual  number  is  at  least  as  large  as  at  any  previous 
date.  It  may  even  be  larger.  See  Labor  in  the  Longest  Reign,  by  Sidney  Webb 
(London,  1897).  How  extensive  is  the  area  occupied  by  low-paid  occupations 
may  be  inferred  from  Mr.  Charles  Booth's  careful  summary  of  his  researches  into 
the  economic  condition  of  London's  4^  millions.  "The  result  of  all  our 
inquiries  make  it  reasonably  sure  that  one-third  of  the  population  are  on  or  about 
the  line  of  poverty  or  are  below  it,  having  at  most  an  income  which,  one  time 
with  another,  averages  twenty-one  shillings  or  twenty-two  shillings  for  a  small 
family  (or  up  to  twenty-five  or  twenty-six  shillings  for  one  of  larger  size),  and  in 
many  cases  falling  much  below  this  level.  There  may  be  another  third  who  have 
perhaps  ten  shillings  more,  or  taking  the  year  round,  from  twenty-five  to  thirty- 
five  shillings  a  week,  among  whom  would  be  counted,  in  addition  to  wage- 
earners,  many  retail  tradesmen  and  small  masters  ;  and  the  last  third  would  in- 
clude those  who  are  better  off." — Life  and  Labour  of  the  People,  vol.  ix.  p.  427. 


Economic  Characteristics  767 

enforcement  of  a  common  minimum  standard  throughout 
the  trade  not  only  stops  the  degradation,  but  in  every  way 
conduces  to  industrial  efficiency.  Within  a  community,  too, 
in  the  absence  of  regulation,  the  competition  between  trades 
tends  to  the  creation  and  persistence  in  certain  occupations 
of  conditions  of  employment  injurious  to  the  nation  as  a 
whole.  The  remedy  is  to  extend  the  conception  of  the 
Common  Rule  from  the  trade  to  the  whole  community,  and 
by  prescribing  a  National  Minimum,  absolutely  to  prevent 
any  industry  being  carried  on  under  conditions  detrimental 
to  the  public  welfare.1 

This  is,  at  bottom,  the  policy  of  factory  legislation,  now 
adopted  by  every  industrial  country.  But  this  policy  of 
prescribing  minimum  conditions,  below  which  no  employer 
is  allowed  to  drive  even  his  most  necessitous  operatives,  has 
yet  been  only  imperfectly  carried  out.  Factory  legislation 
applies,  usually,  only  to  sanitary  conditions  and,  as  regards 
particular  classes,  to  the  hours  of  labor.  Even  within  this 
limited  sphere  it  is  everywhere  unsystematic  and  lop-sided. 
When  any  European  statesman  makes  up  his  mind  to 
grapple  seriously  with  the  problem  of  the  "  sweated  trades  " 
he  will  have  to  expand  the  Factory  Acts  of  his  country  into 
a  systematic  and  comprehensive  Labor  Code,  prescribing  the 
minimum  conditions  under  which  the  community  can  afford 
to  allow  industry  to  be  carried  on ;  and  including  not 
merely  definite  precautions  of  sanitation  and  safety,  and 
maximum  hours  of  toil,  but  also  a  minimum  of  weekly 
earnings.  We  do  not  wish  to  enter  here  upon  the  compli- 
cated issues  of  industrial  politics  in  each  country,  nor  to 

1  The  majority  of  English  statesmen  are  convinced  that  France  and  Germany 
in  giving  bounties  out  of  the  taxes  to  the  manufacturers  of  sugar,  are  impoverish- 
ing their  respective  communities,  to  the  advantage  of  the  consumers — often  the 
foreign  consumers — of  the  sugar.  Yet  the  cost  to  France  and  Germany  of  this 
policy  is  merely  a  definite  annual  sum,  equivalent  to  the  destruction  of  an  iron- 
rlad  or  two.  If  we  allow  an  industry  to  grow  up,  which  habitually  takes  more 
out  of  its  workers  than  the  wages  and  other  conditions  of  employment  enable 
them  to  repair, — still  more,  if  the  effect  of  the  employment  is  to  deteriorate  both 
character  and  physique  of  successive  relays  of  operatives,  who  are  flung  eventually 
on  the  human  rubbish-heap  of  charity  or  the  Poor  Law — is  not  the  nation  paying 
to  that  industry  a  bounty  far  more  serious  in  its  cost  than  any  money  grant  ? 


768  Trade  Union  Theory 

discuss  the  practical  difficulties  and  political  obstacles  which 
everywhere  impede  the  reform  and  extension  of  the  factory 
laws.  But  to  complete  our  economic  analysis  we  must  con- 
sider what  developments  of  the  Trade  Union  Method  ot 
Legal  Enactment  would  be  implied  by  a  systematic  applica- 
tion of  the  conception  of  a  National  Minimum,  and  how  this 
might  be  expected  to  affect  the  evils  that  we  have  described. 
One  of  the  most  obvious  forms  of  industrial  parasitism 
is  the  employment  of  child-labor.  The  early  textile  manu- 
facturer found  that  it  paid  best  to  run  his  mill  almost 
exclusively  by  young  children,  whom  he  employed  without 
regard  to  what  was  to  become  of  them  when  they  grew  too 
big  to  creep  under  his  machines,  and  when  they  required 
more  wages  than  his  labor  bill  allowed.  The  resulting 
degeneracy  of  the  manufacturing  population  became  so 
apparent  that  Parliament,  in  spite  of  all  its  prepossessions, 
was  driven  to  interfere.  The  Yorkshire  Woollen  Workers 
were  seeking,  like  the  Flint  Glass  Makers  of  to-day,  to  meet 
the  case  by  reviving  the  old  period  of  educational  servitude. 
The  Calico-printers  were  aiming,  like  the  National  Union  of 
Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives  before  Lord  James,  at  a  simple 
limitation  of  the  number  of  boys  to  be  employed.1  Neither 
of  these  expedients  was  considered  practicable.  An  alterna- 
tive remedy  was  found  in  prohibiting  the  manufacturer  from 

1  Mimites  of  Evidence  and  Report  of  the  Committee  on  the  Petition  of  the 
Journeymen  Calico -printers,  4th  July  1804,  i;th  July  1806;  Hansard's  Parlia- 
mentary Debates,  vol.  ix.  pp.  534-538  ;  History  of  Trade  Unionism,  p.  50.  Our 
analysis  of  the  economic  competition  between  trades  enables  us  to  see  that  no 
merely  sectional  measure  would  be  of  use  against  an  illegitimate  use  of  boy-labor. 
For  it  is  not  only  the  adult  workers  of  the  particular  trade  who  are  injured.  In 
the  competition  of  trade  with  trade,  whether  for  home  or  foreign  markets,  the 
illegitimate  expansion  of  a  bounty-fed  industry  necessarily  implies  a  relative  con- 
traction of  other  and  possibly  quite  unrelated  trades.  It  is  therefore  not  only, 
and  perhaps  not  even  principally,  the  adult  boot  and  shoe  operatives  who  are 
injured  by  the  undue  multiplication  of  boys  in  the  great  boot  factories  ;  such 
trades  as  the  Flint  Glass  Makers,  who  succeed  in  rigidly  limiting  their  own 
apprentices,  and  agriculture,  which  receives  the  residuum  of  boys,  probably 
suffer  equally,  though  in  a  more  indirect  way,  from  the  fact  that  the  boot  and 
shoe  trade  receives  this  subsidy  in  aid  of  its  own  export  trade,  and  thus  encourages 
an  increase  of  foreign  imports  which  happen  to  come  in  the  form  of  German  glass 
and  American  food  stuffs. 


Economic  Characteristics  769 

employing  children  below  a  certain  age,  and  requiring  him 
to  see  that,  up  to  a  farther  period,  they  spent  half  their  days 
at  school.  The  Factory  Acts  have,  as  regards  children,  long 
since  won  their  way  to  universal  approval,  not  merely  on 
humanitarian  grounds,  but  as  positively  conducive  to  the 
industrial  efficiency  of  the  community.  There  is,  however, 
still  much  to  be  done  before  the  "  Children's  Charter  "  can  be 
said  effectually  to  prevent  all  parasitic  use  of  child -labor. 
Though  children  may  not  be  employed  in  factories  until 
eleven  years  of  age,  nor  full  time  until  they  are  thirteen  or 
fourteen,  they  are  allowed  to  work  at  other  occupations  at 
earlier  ages.  "  In  certain  districts  of  England  and  Wales, 
if  a  child  of  ten  has  obtained  a  certificate  of  previous  due 
attendance  [at  school]  for  five  years,  he  may  be  employed 
elsewhere  than  in  a  factory,  workshop,  or  mine  without  any 
farther  educational  test  or  condition,  and  without  any  restric- 
tion as  to  the  number  of  hours"1  Even  if  the  law  with 
regard  to  the  employment  of  children  in  factories  were  made 
uniformly  applicable  to  all  occupations  in  all  parts  of  the 
United  Kingdom,  the  present  limits  of  age  are  obviously 
inadequate  to  prevent  parasitism.  England  has,  in  this 
respect,  lost  its  honorable  lead  in  protective  legislation,  and 
we  ought  at  once  to  raise  the  age  at  which  any  boy  or  girl 
may  enter  industrial  life  to  the  fourteen  years  already 
adopted  by  the  Swiss  federal  code,2  if  not  to  the  fifteen 
years  now  in  force  in  Geneva,  and  eventually  to  the  sixteen 
years  demanded  by  the  International  Socialist  and  Trade 
Union  Congress  of  1896.  It  is,  however,  in  an  extension  of 
the  half-time  system  that  we  are  likely  to  find  the  most 
effective  check  on  child  -  labor.  We  have  already  seen 
reason  to  believe  that  the  only  way  in  which  proper  technical 
training  can  now  be  secured  for  the  great  mass  of  the  people 

1  Report  of  Departmental  Committee  appointed  to  Inquire  into  the  Conditions 
of  School  Attendance  and  Child-Labor,  H.   C.  No.   311    of  1893,  P-   25-      ^n 
Ireland  school  attendance  is  compulsory  only  in  the  towns,  and  hence  children  of 
any  age  may  lawfully  be  employed  in  the  country  districts  for  any  number  of 
hours,  night  or  day,  otherwise  than  in  factories,  workshops,  or  mines. 

2  Swiss  Federal  Factory  Law  of  23rd  March  1877. 

VOL.  IT  3D 


77O  Trade  Union  Theory 

is  by  their  deliberate  instruction  in  educational  institutions. 
Such  instruction  can  never  be  thoroughly  utilised  so  long  as 
the  youth  has  to  perform  a  full  and  exhausting  day's  work 
at  the  factory  or  the  mine.  There  is  much  to  be  said,  both 
from  an  educational  and  from  a  purely  commercial  point  of 
view,  for  such  a  gradual  extension  of  the  half-time  system  as 
would  put  off  until  eighteen  the  working  of  full  factory 
hours,  in  order  to  allow  of  a  compulsory  attendance  at  the 
technical  school  and  the  continuation  classes.  Any  such 
proposal  would,  at  present,  meet  with  great  opposition  from 
parents  objecting  to  be  deprived  of  their  children's  earnings. 
Some  of  the  more  thoughtful  Trade  Unionists  are,  however, 
beginning  to  see  that  such  a  development  of  the  half-time 
system,  whilst  affording  the  only  practical  substitute  for  the 
apprenticeship  training,  would  have  the  incidental  advantage 
of  placing,  in  the  most  legitimate  way,  an  effective  check  on 
any  excessive  use  of  boy-labor  by  the  employers.1  With 
the  contraction  of  the  supply  the  rate  of  boy's  wages  would 
rise,  so  that  little  less  might  even  be  earned  for  the  half  day 
than  formerly  for  full  time.  Boy  -  labor,  therefore,  would 
become  less  profitable  to  the  employers,  and  would  tend  to 
be  used  by  them  only  for  its  legitimate  purpose  of  training 
up  a  new  generation  of  adult  workmen.2  To  prevent  para- 
sitism, in  short,  we  must  regard  the  boy  or  girl,  not  as  an 

1  See,  for  instance,  the  Report  of  the  Trade  Unionist  Minority  of  the  Royal 
Commission  on  Labor  ^  in  C.  7421,  1894.     A  somewhat  analogous  arrangement 
is  already  in  force  in  Neuchatel,  under  its  Apprenticeship  Law  of  1891,  and  in 
some  other  Swiss  cantons. 

2  It  might  even  become  necessary  for  the  community  to  pay  a  premium  for 
the  proper  technical  education  of  boys  in  trades  in  which  employers  preferred 
altogether  to  dispense  with  them.     Under  private  enterprise  it  requires  a  certain 
foresight  and  permanence  of  interest  for  individual  employers  to  have  any  regard 
for  the  rearing  up  of  new  generations  of  skilled  operatives.      Thus,  whilst  some 
of  the  best  shipbuilding  establishments  in  the  North  of  England  bestow  consider- 
able attention  on  their  apprentices,   the   rule  in    the  Midland  boot    and   shoe 
factories  is,    as  we  have  seen,   to  teach  the  boys  practically  nothing,  and    the 
London  builders  have  left  off  employing  boys  at  all.      It  was  found  that,  in  1895. 
41   typical  London  firms  in  various  branches  of  the  building  trades,  employing 
12,000  journeymen,  had  only  80  apprentices  and   143  other  "learners"  in  their 
establishments.      (See  the  report  of  an  inquiry  into  apprenticeship  in  the  London 
building  trades  conducted  by  the  Technical  Education  Board,  published  in  the 
London  Technical  Education  Gazette,  October  1895.) 


Economic  Characteristics  771 

independent  wealth-producer  to  be  satisfied  by  a  daily  sub- 
sistence, but  as  the  future  citizen  and  parent,  for  whom,  up 
to  twenty-one,  proper  conditions  of  growth  and  education 
are  of  paramount  importance.  Hence  the  Policy  of  a 
National  Minimum — the  prohibition  of  all  such  conditions 
of  employment  as  are  inconsistent  with  the  maintenance  of 
the  workers  in  a  state  of  efficiency  as  producers  and  citizens 
— means,  in  the  case  of  a  child  or  a  youth,  the  requirement 
not  merely  of  daily  subsistence  and  pocket-money,  but  also 
of  such  conditions  of  nurture  as  will  ensure  the  continuous 
provision,  generation  after  generation,  of  healthy  and  efficient 
adults. 

In  the  case  of  adults,  parasitism  takes  the  form,  if  we 
may  cite  once  more  the  unimpeachable  testimony  of  the 
House  of  Lords,  of  "  earnings  barely  sufficient  to  sustain 
existence  ;  hours  of  labor  such  as  to  make  the  lives  of  the 
workers  periods  of  almost  ceaseless  toil,  hard  and  unlovely 
to  the  last  degree  ;  sanitary  conditions  injurious  to  the  health 
of  the  persons  employed  and  dangerous  to  the  public." 1 
Each  of  these  points  requires  separate  consideration. 

With  regard  to  sanitation,  the  law  of  the  United  Kingdom 
already  professes  to  secure  to  every  manufacturing  operative, 
whether  employed  in  a  factory  or  a  workshop,  and  whether 
man  or  woman,  reasonably  healthy  conditions  of  employ- 
ment. In  addition  to  the  general  requirements  of  the  Public 
Health  Acts,  the  employer  has  put  upon  him,  by  the  Factory 
Acts,  as  a  condition  of  being  allowed  to  carry  on  his  industry, 
the  obligation  of  providing  and  maintaining  whatever  is 
necessary  for  the  sanitation  and  safety  of  all  the  persons 
whom  he  employs  whilst  they  are  at  work  on  his  premises. 
If  the  industry  is  one  by  its  very  nature  unhealthy,  the  em- 
ployer is  required  to  take  the  technical  precautions  deemed 
necessary  by  the  scientific  experts,  and  prescribed  by  special 
rules  for  each  occupation.  So  far  the  Policy  of  a  National 
Minimum  of  Sanitation  would  seem  to  be  already  embodied 

1  Final  Report  of  the  Select  Committee  of  the  House  of  Lords  on  the  Sweating 
System,  1890. 


772  Trade  Union  Theory 

in  English  law.  But  appearances  are  deceptive.  Whole 
classes  of  industrial  wage-earners  find  themselves  entirely 
outside  the  Factory  Acts,  whilst  even  of  those  who  are 
nominally  included,  large  sections  are,  in  one  way  or  another, 
deprived  of  any  real  protection.  Hence,  far  from  securing 
a  National  Minimum  of  Sanitation  and  Safety  to  every  one, 
the  law  is  at  present  only  brought  effectively  into  force  to 
protect  the  conditions  of  employment  of  the  strongest  sections 
of  the  wage-earners,  notably  the  Coal  miners  and  the  Cotton 
Operatives,  whilst  the  weakest  sections  of  all,  notably  the 
outworkers  of  the  "  sweated  trades,"  remain  as  much  oppressed 
in  the  way  of  sanitation  as  they  are  in  hours  of  labor 
and  wages.  If  it  is  desired  to  carry  out  the  Policy  of  a 
National  Minimum  on  this  point,  Parliament  will  have  to 
make  all  employers,  whether  factory-owners,  small  workshop 
masters,  or  traders  giving  out  material  to  be  made  up  else- 
where, equally  responsible  for  the  sanitary  conditions  under 
which  their  work  is  done.1 

When  we  turn  from  sanitation  to  the  equally  indispens- 
able conditions  of  leisure  and  rest,  English  factory  legislation 
is  still  more  imperfect.  It  has  for  fifty  years  been  accepted 
that  it  is  against  public  policy  for  women  to  be  kept  to 
manual  labor  for  more  than  sixty  hours  a  week,  and  this 
principle  is  supposed  to  be  embodied  in  the  law.  But  here 
again,  the  most  oppressed  classes — the  women  working  day 
and  night  for  the  wholesale  clothiers,  or  kept  standing  all 
day  long  behind  the  counter  of  a  shop  or  the  bar  of  a  public- 
house — who  are  absolutely  excluded  from  the  scope  of  the 
law.  Even  where  the  law  applies,  it  applies  least  thoroughly 
in  the  most  helpless  trades.  We  have  already  described 

1  A  beginning  has  been  made  by  the  sections  of  the  Factory  Acts  of  1891 
and  1895  imposing  upon  persons  giving  out  work  to  be  done  elsewhere  than  on 
their  own  premises  certain  obligations  with  regard  to  the  sanitary  conditions  of 
their  outworkers.  In  their  present  form,  however,  these  sections  are  admittedly 
unworkable,  and  no  serious  effort  has  yet  been  made  to  cope  with  the  evils 
revealed  by  the  House  of  Lords'  Committee  on  the  Sweating  System  in  1890. 
See  Sweating,  its  Cause  and  Remedy  (Fabian  Tract,  No.  50),  How  to  do  away 
with  the  Sweating  System,  by  Beatrice  Potter  (Mrs.  Sidney  Webb)  (Co-operative 
Union  pamphlet),  and  the  Trade  Unionist  Minority  Report  of  the  Royal 
Commission  on  Labor,  in  C.  7421,  1894. 


Economic  Characteristics  773 

how,  in  all  non-textile  industries,  the  overtime  provisions 
destroy  the  efficacy  of  the  Factory  Act,1  and,  in  such  cases 
as  laundry-workers  and  dressmakers  in  small  shops,  render  it 
practically  of  no  avail.  It  is  one  more  instance  of  the  irony 
of  English  labor  legislation  that  the  women  in  the  textile 
mills  have  alone  secured  a  really  effective  limitation  of  their 
hours  of  labor,  and  this  as  low  as  56^-  hours  a  week,  in 
spite  of  the  fact  that  they  are,  of  all  women  workers,  the 
least  helpless  and,  as  a  class,  the  best  off.  And  when  we 
pass  from  women  to  men,  the  statute  book  with  regard  to 
the  hours  of  labor  is  at  present  a  blank,  relieved  only  by  the 
tentative  provisions  of  the  Railway  Regulation  Act  of  1893. 
Before  we  can  be  said  to  have  established  a  National  Mini- 
mum of  leisure  and  rest,  the  provisions  of  the  Factory  Acts 
with  regard  to  textile  factories  will  have  to  be  made  appli- 
cable, with  the  special  modifications  appropriate  to  each 
particular  occupation,  to  all  manual  workers  whatsoever. 

But  sanitation  and  leisure  do  not,  of  themselves,  maintain 
the  nation's  workers  in  health  and  efficiency,  or  prevent 
industrial  parasitism.  Just  as  it  is  against  public  policy  to 
allow  an  employer  to  engage  a  woman  to  work  excessive 
hours  or  under  insanitary  conditions,  so  it  is  equally  against 
public  policy  to  permit  him  to  engage  her  for  wages  in- 
sufficient to  provide  the  food  and  shelter,  without  which  she 
cannot  continue  in  health.  Once  we  begin  to  prescribe  the 
minimum  conditions  under  which  an  employer  should  be 
permitted  to  open  a  factory,  there  is  no  logical  distinction 
to  be  drawn  between  the  several  clauses  of  the  wage 
contract.  From  the  point  of  view  of  the  employer,  one 
way  of  increasing  the  cost  of  production  is  the  same  as 
another,  whilst  to  the  economist  and  the  statesman,  con- 
cerned with  the  permanent  efficiency  of  industry  and  the 
maintenance  of  national  health,  adequate  food  is  at  least  as 
important  as  reasonable  hours  or  good  drainage.  To  be 
completely  effectual,  the  Policy  of  the  National  Minimum 
will,  therefore,  have  to  be  applied  to  wages. 

1  See  a  preceding  chapter  on  "The  Normal  Day." 


774  Trade  Union  J^heory 

The  proposition  of  a  National  Minimum  of  wages — the 
enactment  of  a  definite  sum  of  earnings  per  week  below  which 
no  employer  should  be  allowed  to  hire  any  worker — has  not 
yet  been  put  forward  by  any  considerable  section  of  Trade 
Unionists,  nor  taken  into  consideration  by  any  Home 
Secretary.  This  reluctance  to  pass  to  the  obvious  com- 
pletion of  the  policy  of  factory  legislation,  at  once  logical 
and  practical,  arises,  we  think,  from  a  shrinking,  both  on  the 
part  of  workmen  and  employers,  from  having  all  wages  fixed 
by  law.  But  this  is  quite  a  different  proposition.  The 
fixing  of  a  National  Minimum  of  Sanitation  has  not  pre- 
vented the  erection  in  our  great  industrial  centres  of  work- 
places which,  compared  with  the  minimum  prescribed  by  the 
law,  are  palatial  in  their  provision  of  light,  air,  cubic  space, 
warmth,  and  sanitary  accommodation.  And  a  National 
Minimum  of  leisure  and  rest,  fixed,  for  instance,  at  the  textile 
standard  of  56^  hours'  work  a  week,  would  in  no  way 
interfere  with  the  Northumberland  Coalminers  maintaining 
their  37  hours'  week,  or  the  London  Engineers  bargaining 
for  a  48  hours'  week.  There  is  even  less  reason  why,  with 
regard  to  wages,  the  enactment  of  a  National  Minimum 
should  interfere  with  the  higher  rates  actually  existing,  or  in 
future  obtained,  in  the  tens  of  thousands  of  distinct  occupa- 
tions throughout  the  country.  The  fact  that  the  Committees 
of  the  London  County  Council  are  precluded,  by  its  Standing 
Orders,  from  employing  any  workman  at  less  than  245.  a 
week,  does  not  prevent  their  engaging  workmen  at  all  sorts 
of  higher  rates,  according  to  agreement.  And  if  the  House 
of  Commons  were  to  replace  its  present  platonic  declaration 
against  the  evils  of  sweating  by  an  effective  minimum,  the 
superintendents  of  the  various  Government  departments 
would  still  go  on  paying  their  higher  rates  to  all  but  the 
lowest  grade  of  workmen. 

The  object  of  the  National  Minimum  being  to  secure  the 
community  against  the  evils  of  industrial  parasitism,  the 
minimum  wage  for  a  man  or  a  woman  respectively  would  be 
determiced  by  practical  inquiry  as  to  the  cost  of  the  food. 


Economic  Characteristics  775 

clothing,  and  shelter  physiologically  necessary,  according  to 
national  habit  and  custom,  to  prevent  bodily  deterioration. 
Such  a  minimum  would  therefore  be  low,  and  though  its 
establishment  would  be  welcomed  as  a  boon  by  the  unskilled 
workers  in  the  unregulated  trades,  it  would  not  at  all  corre- 
spond with  the  conception  of  a  "  Living  Wage "  formed  by 
the  Cotton  Operatives  or  the  Coalminers.  It  would  be  a 
matter  for  careful  consideration  what  relation  the  National 
Minimum  for  adult  men  should  bear  to  that  for  adult  women ; 
what  differences,  if  any,  should  be  made  between  town  and 
country ;  and  whether  the  standard  should  be  fixed  by 
national  authority  (like  the  hours  of  labor  for  young  persons 
and  women),  or  by  local  authority  (like  the  educational 
qualification  for  child  -  labor).  To  those  not  practically 
acquainted  with  the  organisation  of  English  industry  and 
Government  administration,  the  idea  will  seem  impracticable. 
But,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  the  authoritative  settlement  of  a 
minimum  wage  is  already  daily  undertaken.  Every  local 
governing  body  throughout  the  country  has  to  decide  under 
the  criticism  of  public  opinion  what  wage  it  will  pay  to  its 
lowest  grade  of  laborers.  It  can  hire  them  at  any  price, 
even  at  a  shilling  a  day  ;  but  what  happens  in  practice 
is  that  the  officer  in  charge  fixes  such  a  wage  as  he  believes 
he  can  permanently  get  good  enough  work  for.  In  the  same 
way  the  national  Government,  which  is  by  far  the  largest 
employer  of  labor  in  the  country,  does  not  take  the  cheapest 
laborers  it  can  get,  at  the  lowest  price  for  which  they  will 
offer  themselves,  but  deliberately  settles  its  own  minimum 
wage  for  each  department.  During  the  last  few  years  this 
systematic  determination  of  the  rate  to  be  paid  for  Govern- 
ment labor,  which  must  have  existed  since  the  days  of  Pepys, 
has  been  more  and  more  consciously  based  upon  what  we 
have  called  the  Doctrine  of  a  Living  Wage.  Thus  the 
Admiralty  is  now  constantly  taking  evidence,  either  through 
the  Labor  Department  or  through  its  own  officials,  as  to  the 
cost  of  living  in  different  localities,  so  as  to  adjust  its  laborers' 
wages  to  the  expense  of  their  subsistence.  And  in  our 


776  Trade  Union  Theory 

local  governing  bodies  we  see  the  committees,  under  the 
pressure  of  public  opinion,  every  day  substituting  a  deliber- 
ately settled  minimum  for  the  haphazard  decisions  of  the 
officials  of  the  several  departments.1  What  is  not  so 
generally  recognised  is  that  exactly  the  same  change  is 
taking  place  in  private  enterprise.  The  great  captains  of 
industry,  interested  in  the  permanent  efficiency  of  their  estab- 
lishments, have  long  adopted  the  practice  of  deliberately 
fixing  the  minimum  wage  to  be  paid  to  the  lowest  class  of 
unskilled  laborers,  according  to  their  own  view  of  what  the 
laborers  can  live  on,  instead  of  letting  out  their  work  to  sub- 
contractors, whose  only  object  is  to  exact  the  utmost  exertion 
for  the  lowest  price.  A  railway  company  never  dreams  of 
putting  its  situations  out  to  tender,  and  engaging  the  man 
who  offers  to  come  at  the  lowest  wage :  what  happens  is 
that  the  rate  of  pay  of  porters  and  shunters  is  deliberately 
fixed  in  advance.  And  it  is  a  marked  feature  of  the  last 
ten  years  that  the  settlement  of  this  minimum  has  been,  in 
some  of  the  greatest  industries,  taken  out  of  the  hands  of  the 
individual  employer,  and  arrived  at  by  an  arbitrator.  The 
assumption  that  the  wages  of  the  lowest  grade  of  labor  must 
at  any  rate  be  enough  to  maintain  the  laborer  in  industrial 
efficiency  is,  in  fact,  accepted  by  both  parties,  so  that  the 
task  of  the  arbitrator  is  comparatively  easy.  Lord  James, 
for  instance,  has  lately  fixed,  with  universal  acceptance,  a 
minimum  wage  for  all  the  lowlier  grades  of  labor  employed 

1  An  interesting  survey  of  the  steps  taken  to  secure  the  payment  of  the 
Standard  Rate  to  persons  working  for  public  authorities  in  France,  the  United 
Kingdom,  Belgium,  Holland,  Italy,  and  Switzerland,  is  given  by  Auguste  Keufer 
in  his  Rapport  tendant  a  rechercher  les  may  ens  de  parer  aux  funestes  consequences 
du  systeme  actuel  des  adjudications  (Paris,  1896,  48  pp.)-  See  also  Louis  Katzen- 
stein,  Die  Lohnfrage  unter  dem  Englischen  Submissionswesen  (Berlin,  1896) ; 
the  important  Enquete  of  the  Communal  Council  of  Brussels  into  the  effect  of 
fixing  and  of  not  fixing  the  rates  of  wages  payable  in  public  contract  works, 
2  vols.  (Brussels,  1896) ;  and  the  Report  of  the  House  of  Commons'  Committee  on 
the  Conditions  of  Government  Contracts  (H.  C.  334),  July  1897. 

In  order  to  put  a  stop  to  the  practice  of  engaging  learners  or  improvers  with- 
out any  salary  whatsoever,  the  Victorian  Factories  and  Shops  Act  of  1896  (No. 
1445)  enacts  (sec.  16)  that  "no  person  whatsoever,  unless  in  receipt  of  a  weekly 
wage  of  at  least  two  shillings  and  sixpence,  shall  be  employed  in  any  factory  or 
workroom." 


Economic  Characteristics  777 

by  the  North  Eastern  Railway  Company.1  Indeed,  the 
fixing  of  a  minimum  wage  on  physiological  grounds  is  a 
less  complicated  matter,  and  one  demanding  less  techno- 
logical knowledge  than  the  fixing  of  a  minimum  of  sanitation  ; 
and  it  interferes  far  less  with  the  day-by-day  management  of 
industry,  or  its  productivity,  than  any  fixing  of  the  hours  of 
labor,  whether  of  women  or  men.  To  put  it  concretely,  if 
Colonel  Dyer  (of  Armstrong's)  and  Mr.  Livesey  (of  the  South 
Metropolitan  Gas  Works)  could  for  a  moment  rid  themselves 
of  their  metaphysical  horror  of  any  legal  regulation  of  wages, 
they  would  admit  that  the  elaborate  Factory  Act  require- 
ments in  the  way  of  Sanitation  and  Safety,  and  any  limita- 
tion of  the  Hours  of  Labor,  constitute  a  far  greater  impediment 
to  their  management  of  their  own  business  in  the  way  they 
think  best  than  would  any  National  Minimum  of  wages  for 
the  lowest  grade  of  labor.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  what  would 
happen  would  be  the  adoption,  as  the  National  Minimum,  of 
the  wages  actually  paid  by  the  better  establishments,  who 
would  accordingly  be  affected  only  to  the  extent  of  finding 
their  competitors  put  on  the  same  level  as  themselves.2 

More  formidable  than  any  a  priori  objection  to  the 
National  Minimum  on  the  part  of  employers  who  would 
really  be  unaffected  by  it,  would  be  the  vehement  obstruction 
that  any  such  proposal  would  meet  with  from  the  profit- 

1  See  his  award  in  the  Labour  Gazette  for  August  1897. 

2  We  desire  to  emphasise  the  point  that,  whatever  political  objections  there 
may  be   to   the    fixing  by  law  of  a  National   Minimum  Wage,  and   whatever 
practical  difficulties  there  may  be  in  carrying  it  out,  the  proposal,  from  the  point 
of  view  of  abstract  economics,  is  open  to  no  more  objection  than  the  fixing  by  law 
of  a  National  Minimum  of  Sanitation,  or  a  National  Minimum  of  Leisure,  both 
of  which    are,  in    principle,  embodied   in    our   factory  legislation.      Indeed,  a 
minimum   wage,    since    it    could    in    no  way  interfere   with    the    fullest  use  of 
machinery  and  plant,  or  otherwise  check   productivity,  would  seem  to  be  even 
less  open  to  economic  criticism  than  a  limitation  of  the  hours  of  labor. 

It  must  not  be  supposed  that  the  National  Minimum  of  wages  would 
necessarily  involve  payment  by  time.  There  would  be  no  objection  to  its  taking 
the  form  of  Standard  Piecework  Lists,  provided  that  these  were  combined,  as 
they  always  are  in  efficient  Trade  Unions,  with  a  guarantee  that,  so  long  as  an 
operative  is  in  the  employer's  service,  he  must  be  provided  each  week  with 
sufficient  work  at  the  Standard  Piece  Rate  to  make  up  the  minimum  weekly 
earnings,  or  be  paid  for  his  time. 


778  Trade  Union  Theory 

makers  in  the  parasitic  trades.  This  obstruction  would 
inevitably  concentrate  itself  into  two  main  arguments.  They 
would  assert  that  if  they  had  to  give  decent  conditions  to 
every  person  they  employed,  their  trade  would  at  once 
becoare  unprofitable,  and  would  either  cease  to  exist,  or  be 
out  of  the  country.  And,  quite  apart  from  this 
rinking  of  the  area  of  employment,  what,  they  would  ask, 
would  become  of  the  feeble  and  inefficient,  the  infirm  and 
the  aged,  the  "  workers  without  a  character,"  or  the  "  poor 
widows,"  who  now  pick  up  some  kind  (that  is,  some  part)  of 
a  livelihood,  and  who  would  inevitably  be  not  worth  employ- 
ing at  all  if  they  had  to  be  paid  the  National  Minimum 
wage  ? 

The  enactment  of  a  National  Minimum  would  by  no 
means  necessarily  involve  the  destruction  of  the  trades  at 
present  carried  on  by  parasitic  labor.  When  any  particular 
way  of  carrying  on  an  industry  is  favored  by  a  bounty  or 
subsidy,  this  way  will  almost  certainly  be  chosen,  to  the 
exclusion  of  other  methods  of  conducting  the  business.  If 
the  subsidy  is  withdrawn,  it  often  happens  that  the  industry 
falls  back  on  another  process  which,  less  immediately  pro- 
fitable to  the  capitalists  than  the  bounty-fed  method,  proves 
positively  more  advantageous  to  the  industry  in  the  long 
run.  This  result,  familiar  to  the  Free  Trader,  is  even  more 
probable  when  the  bounty  or  subsidy  takes  the  form,  not  of 
a  protective  tariff,  an  exemption  from  taxation,  or  a  direct 
money  grant,  but  the  privilege  of  exacting  from  the  manual 
workers  more  labor-force  than  is  replaced  by  the  wages  and 
other  conditions  of  employment.  The  existence  of  negro 
slavery  in  the  Southern  States  of  America  made,  while  it 
lasted,  any  other  method  of  carrying  on  industry  economically 
impossible  ;  but  it  was  not  really  an  economic  advantage  to 
cotton-growing.  The  "  white  slavery  "  of  the  early  factory 
system  stood,  so  long  as  it  was  permitted,  in  the  way  of  any 
manufacturer  adopting  more  humane  conditions  of  employ- 
ment ;  but  when  the  Lancashire  millowners  had  these  more 
humane  conditions  forced  upon  them,  they  were  discovered 


Economic  Characteristics  779 

to  be  more  profitable  than  those  which  unlimited  freedom  oi 
competition  had  dictated.  There  is  much  reason  to  believe 
that  the  low  wages  to  which,  in  the  unregulated  trades, 
the  stream  of  competitive  pressure  forces  employers  and 
operatives  alike,  are  not  in  themselves  any  more  econo- 
mically advantageous  to  the  industry  than  the  long  hours 
and  absence  of  sanitary  precautions  were  to  the  early 
cotton  mills  of  Lancashire.  To  put  it  plumply,  if  the 
employers  paid  more,  the  labor  would  quickly  be  worth 
more.  In  so  far  as  this  proved  to  be  the  case,  the  National 
Minimum  would  have  raised  the  Standard  of  Life  without 
loss  of  work,  without  cost  to  the  employer,  and  without 
disadvantage  to  the  community.  Moreover,  the  mere  fact 
that  employers  are  at  present  paying  lower  wages  than  the 
proposed  minimum  is  no  proof  that  the  labor  is  not  "  worth  " 
more  to  them  and  to  the  customers  ;  for  the  wages  of  the 
lowest  grade  of  labor  are  fixed,  not  by  the  worth  of  the 
individual  laborer,  but  largely  by  the  necessities  of  the 
marginal  man.  It  may  well  be  that,  rather  than  go  without 
the  particular  commodity  produced,  the  community  would 
willingly  pay  more  for  it.  Nevertheless,  so  long  as  the 
wage-earner  can  be  squeezed  down  to  a  subsistence  or, 
more  correctly,  a  parasitic  wage,  the  pressure  of  competi- 
tion will  compel  the  employer  so  to  squeeze  him,  whether 
the  consumer  desires  it  or  not. 

It  may,  however,  be  admitted  that  a  prohibition  of 
parasitism  would  have  the  effect  of  restricting  certain  in- 
dustries. The  ablest,  best-equipped,  and  best  situated 
employers  would  find  themselves  able  to  go  on  under  the 
new  conditions,  and  would  even  profit  by  the  change.  The 
firms  just  struggling  on  the  margin  would  probably  go 
under.  It  might  even  happen  that  particular  branches  of 
the  sweated  trades  would  fall  into  the  hands  of  other 
countries.  If  the  French  Government  withdrew  its  pre- 
sent bounties  on  the  production  of  sugar,  some  French 
establishments  would  certainly  be  shut  up,  and  the  total 
exports  of  French  sugar,  other  things  remaining  equal, 


780  Trade  Union  Theory 

would  be  diminished.  But  all  economists  will  agree  that 
the  mere  keeping  alive  a  trade  by  a  bounty,  whatever  other 
advantages  it  may  be  supposed  to  have,  does  not,  of  itself, 
aggregate  trade  of  the  country,  or  the  area  of 
employment.  What  the  bounty  does  is  to  divert  to  sugar 
Production  capital  and  labor  which  would  otherwise  have 
been  devoted  to  the  production  of  other  articles,  presumably 
to  greater  profit,  for  otherwise  the  bounty  would  not  have 
been  required.  When  the  bounty  is  withdrawn  this  diver- 
sion ceases,  and  the  available  capital  and  labor  is  re-distrib- 
uted over  the  nation's  industry  in  the  more  profitable  way. 
And  if  it  be  replied  that  there  will  be  no  demand  for  these 
other  articles,  the  answer  is  clear.  If  the  bounty-fed  sugar 
ceases  to  be  exported,  the  commodities  given  in  exchange 
for  it  cease  to  be  imported,  and  have  to  be  produced  at 
home.  The  capital  and  labor  which  formerly  produced 
sugar  is  now  free  to  produce  the  commodities  which  were 
formerly  obtained  by  the  export  of  the  sugar.  In  short,  the 
aggregate  product  remaining  the  same,  the  aggregate  demand 
cannot  be  lessened,  for  they  are  but  different  aspects  of  one 
and  the  same  thing. 

Exactly  the  same  reasoning  holds  good  with  regard  to 
what  we  have  called  the  parasitic  trades.  Assuming  that 
the  employers  in  these  trades  have  hitherto  been  getting 
more  labor-force  than  their  wages  have  been  replacing,  any 
effective  enforcement  of  a  National  Minimum  of  conditions 
of  employment  would  be  equivalent  to  a  simple  withdrawal 
of  a  bounty.  We  should,  therefore,  expect  to  see  a 
shrinkage  in  these  trades.  But  there  would  be  at  least  a 
corresponding  expansion  in  others.  Let  us,  for  instance, 
imagine  that  the  wholesale  clothiers  are  compelled  to  give 
decent  conditions  to  all  their  outworkers.  It  may  be  that 
this  will  cause  a  rise  in  the  cost  of  production  of  certain 
lines  of  clothing.  This  will  certainly  diminish  their  export 
sales,  and  might  even  close  particular  markets  altogether. 
This  check  to  our  export  trade  will  have  one  of  two  results. 
If  our  imports  go  on  undiminished,  the  aggregate  of  our 


Economic  Characteristics  781 

exports  must,  to  meet  our  foreign  indebtedness,  be  made 
up  somehow,  and  international  demand  will  cause  other 
branches  of  our  export  trade  to  expand.  Hence  the  result 
of  destroying  parasitism  in  the  wholesale  clothing  trade 
would,  on  this  hypothesis,  be  to  cause  a  positive  increase  in 
the  exports,  and  thus  in  the  number  of  producers,  of  such 
things  as  textiles,  machinery,  or  coal.  But  it  may  be  urged 
that  the  slackening  of  the  wholesale  clothing  trade  would 
cause  our  imports  to  fall  off.  In  that  case  there  would  at 
last  be  a  gleam  of  hope  for  the  poor  English  farmer,  whose 
sales  would  expand  to  meet  the  demand  formerly  satisfied 
by  foreign  food  stuffs.  Hence  it  follows  that,  whatever  new 
distribution  of  the  nation's  industry  might  be  produced  by 
the  prohibition  of  parasitism,  there  is  no  ground  for  fearing 
that  the  aggregate  production,  and  therefore  either  the 
aggregate  demand  or  the  total  area  of  employment,  would 
be  in  any  way  diminished.1 

1  It  may  be  interesting  to  follow  out  this  argument  to  its  logical  conclusion. 
Let  us  assume  a  country  in  which  all  trades  whatsoever  are  parasitic — that  is  to 
say,  where  every  manual  worker  is  working  under  conditions  which  do  not 
suffice  to  keep  him  permanently  in  industrial  efficiency.  In  this  case  an  enforce- 
ment of  a  National  Minimum  would  necessarily  raise  the  expenses  of  production 
to  the  capitalist  employer  (though  not  the  actual  labor  cost)  of  all  the  commodi- 
ties produced.  The  economist  would  nevertheless  advise  the  adoption  of  the 
policy.  It  would  be  of  vital  importance,  in  the  economic  interests  of  the  com- 
munity as  a  whole,  to  stop  the  social  degradation  and  industrial  deterioration 
implied  by  the  universal  parasitism.  The  increased  cost  of  production,  due  to 
the  stoppage  of  this  drawing  on  the  future,  would  cause  a  general  rise  in  prices. 
It  is  often  assumed  that  such  a  rise  would  counteract  the  advantages  of  the  higher 
wages.  Mr.  Herbert  Spencer,  in  the  concluding  volume  of  his  Synthetic  Philo- 
sophy, naively  makes  this  his  one  economic  objection  to  Trade  Unionism.  "If," 
he  says,  "wages  are  forced  up,  the  price  of  the  article  produced  must  presently 
be  forced  up.  What  then  happens  if,  as  now,  Trade  Unions  are  established 
among  the  workers  in  nearly  all  occupations,  and  if  these  unions  severally  succeed 
in  making  wages  higher  ?  All  the  various  articles  they  are  occupied  in  making 
must  be  raised  in  price ;  and  each  trade  unionist,  while  so  much  the  more  in 
pocket  by  advanced  wages,  is  so  much  the  more  out  of  pocket  by  having  to  buy 
things  at  advanced  rates"  {Industrial  Institutions >  London,  1896,  p.  536).  But 
this  is  to  assume  that  the  wage-earners  purchase  as  consumers  the  whole  of  the 
commodities  and  services  which  they  produce.  We  need  not  remind  the  reader 
that  this  is  untrue.  In  the  United  Kingdom,  for  instance,  though  the  wage- 
earners  number  four-fifths  of  the  population,  they  consume — to  take  the  highest 
estimate  —  only  between  one-third  and  two-fifths  of  the  annual  aggregate  of 
products  and  services,  the  remainder  being  enjoyed  by  the  propertied  classes  and 
the  brain -workers.  Even  if  a  general  rise  in  wages,  amounting  to  say  fifty 


782  Trade  Union  Theory 

The  question  then  arises  what  effect  the  prohibition  of 
parasitism  would  have  on  the  individuals  at  present  working 
in  the  sweated  trades.  We  need  not  dwell  on  the  inevi- 
table personal  hardships  incidental  to  any  shifting  of  in- 
industry  or  change  of  process.  Any  deliberate  improvement 

millions  sterling,  produced  a  general  rise  in  prices  to  the  extent  of  fifty  millions 
sterling,  spread  equally  over  all  products,  it  could  not  be  said  that  the  wage- 
earners  as  a  class  would  have  to  bear  on  their  own  purchases  more  than  one-third 
to  two-fifths  of  this  additional  price.  If  the  rise  in  price  was  not  spread  equally 
over  all  commodities  and  services,  but  occurred  only  in  those  consumed  by  the 
other  classes,  the  rise  in  wages  would  have  been  a  net  gain  to  the  wage-earners. 
Only  in  the  impossible  case  of  the  rise  occurring  exclusively  in  the  commodities 
consumed  by  the  wage-earning  classes — these  commodities  being,  as  we  have 
seen,  only  one-third  to  two-fifths  of  the  whole — would  that  class  find  its  action 
in  raising  wages  nullified  in  the  simple  manner  that  Mr.  Spencer  imagines. 
Hence  it  is,  that  even  if  a  rise  in  the  Standard  of  Life  of  the  whole  wage-earning 
class  produces  an  equivalent  general  rise  in  the  price  of  commodities,  the  result 
must  nevertheless  be  a  net  gain  to  the  wage-earners.  This  process  might, 
theoretically,  be  carried  very  far,  the  ultimate  sufferers  being  the  non-working 
recipients  of  rent  and  interest,  whose  incomes,  nominally  unimpaired,  would 
purchase  progressively  less  of  the  annual  product.  Practically,  however,  any 
indefinite  rise  of  wages  would  be  limited  by  the  impossibility  of  inducing  the 
community  of  citizen-consumers  to  sanction,  in  the  interests  of  the  lowliest 
sections,  anything  in  the  way  of  a  legal  minimum  wage — involving,  as  this  would, 
a  mulcting  of  the  vast  majority  of  the  better-off  purchasers — which  did  not 
commend  itself  to  this  majority  as  being  necessary  to  the  public  welfare. 

Nor  can  it  be  inferred  that  any  such  general  rise  in  the  price  of  labor,  even  if 
it  caused  a  general  rise  in  the  price  of  commodities,  would  adversely  affect  the 
nation's  foreign  trade.  A  rise  in  the  price  of  any  one  commodity  has,  almost 
invariably,  an  immediate  effect  upon  the  volume  of  the  import  or  export  trade  in 
that  commodity.  But  if  the  rise  in  prices  is  general  and  uniform  in  all  the  com- 
modities of  the  community,  the  aggregate  volume  of  the  exports  of  that 
community  will  not  be  diminished  merely  by  reason  of  the  rise.  It  is  a  truism, 
not  only  of  the  academic  economists,  but  also  of  the  practical  financiers  of  all 
nations,  that  the  imports  of  our  country  (together  with  any  other  foreign 
indebtedness)  must,  on  an  average  of  years,  be  paid  for  by  our  exports,  taking 
into  account  any  other  obligations  of  foreigners  to  us.  Any  general  increase  in 
the  cost  of  labor,  such  as  a  rise  in  the  Standard  of  Life,  a  general  advance  of 
factory  legislation,  or  a  universal  Eight  Hours'  Day  if  we  may  assume  for  the 
sake  of  argument  that  this  results  in  a  iiniform  rise  of  prices,  would  leave  our 
annual  indebtedness  to  foreign  countries  undiminished,  even  if  it  did  not  increase 
it  by  temporarily  stimulating  imports.  Hence  it  is  inferred  with  certainty  that  a 
merely  general  and  uniform  rise  in  prices  in  one  country  will  not  prevent  goods 
to  the  same  aggregate  value  as  before  from  being  exported  to  discharge  that 
indebtedness.  To  put  it  shortly,  the  mere  fact  that  the  manual  laborers  receive 
a  larger  proportion,  and  the  directors  of  industry  or  capitalists  a  smaller  propor- 
tion of  the  aggregate  product,  has  no  influence  on  the  total  volume,  or  the 
profitableness  to  the  nation,  of  its  international  trade.  See  Appendix  II.,  in 
which  this  question  is  fully  dealt  with. 


Economic  Characteristics  78  3 

in  the  distribution  of  the  nation's  industry  ought,  therefore,  to 
be  brought  about  gradually,  and  with  equitable  consideration 
of  the  persons  injuriously  affected.  But  there  is  no  need  to 
assume  that  anything  like  all  those  now  receiving  less  than  the 
National  Minimum  would  be  displaced  by  its  enactment. 

We  see,  in  the  first  place,  that  the  very  levelling  up  oi 
the  standard  conditions  of  sanitation,  hours,  and  wages  would, 
in  some  directions,  positively  stimulate  the  demand  for 
labor.  The  contraction  of  the  employment  of  boys  and 
girls,  brought  about  by  the  needful  raising  of  the  age  for 
full  and  half  time  respectively,  would,  in  itself,  increase  the 
number  of  situations  to  be  filled  by  adults.  The  enforce- 
ment of  the  Normal  Day,  by  stopping  the  excessive  hours 
of  labor  now  worked  by  the  most  necessitous  operatives, 
would  tend  to  increase  the  number  employed.  Moreover, 
the  expansion  of  the  self-supporting  trades  which  would,  as 
we  have  seen,  accompany  any  shrinking  of  the  sweated 
industries,  would  automatically  absorb  the  best  of  the  un- 
employed workers  in  their  own  and  allied  occupations,  and 
would  create  a  new  demand  for  learners.  Finally,  the 
abandonment  of  that  irregularity  of  employment  which  so 
disastrously  affects  the  outworkers  and  the  London  dock- 
laborers,  would  result  in  the  enrolment  of  a  new  permanent 
staff.  All  these  changes  would  bring  into  regular  work  at 
or  above  the  National  Minimum  whole  classes  of  operatives, 
selected  from  among  those  now  only  partially  or  fitfully 
employed.  Thus,  all  the  most  capable  and  best  conducted 
would  certainly  obtain  regular  situations.  But  this  con- 
centration of  employment  would  undoubtedly  imply  the 
total  exclusion  of  others  who  might,  in  the  absence  of 
regulation,  have  "  picked  up "  some  sort  of  a  partial 
livelihood.  In  so  far  as  these  permanently  unemployed 
consisted  merely  of  children,  removed  from  industrial 
work  to  the  schoolroom,  few  would  doubt  that  the 
change  would  be  wholly  advantageous.  And  there  are 
many  who  would  welcome  a  re-organisation  of  industry 
which,  by  concentrating  employment  exclusively  among 


784  Trade  Union  Theory 

those  in  regular  attendance,  would  tend  to  exclude  from 
wage -labor,  and  to  set  free  for  domestic  duties,  an  ever- 
increasing  proportion  of  the  women  having  young  children 
to  attend  to.  There  would  still  remain  to  be  considered 
the  remnant  who,  notwithstanding  the  increased  demand  for 
adult  male  labor  and  independent  female  labor,  proved  to  be 
incapable  of  earning  the  National  Minimum  in  any  capacity 
whatsoever.  We  should,  in  fact,  be  brought  face  to  face  with 
the  problem,  not  of  the  unemployed,  but  of  the  unemployable. 


(/")    The  Unemployable 

Here  we  must,  once  for  all,  make  a  distinction  of  vital 
importance :  we  must  mark  off  the  Unemployable  from 
the  temporarily  unemployed.  The  case  of  the  workman, 
normally  able  to  earn  his  own  living,  who  is  unemployed 
merely  because  there  is,  for  the  moment,  no  work  for  him  to 
do,  stands  on  an  altogether  different  plane  from  that  of  the 
man  who  is  unemployed  because  he  is  at  all  times  incapable 
of  holding  a  regular  situation,  and  producing  a  complete 
maintenance.  Periods  of  unemployment,  if  only  while 
shifting  from  job  to  job,  are,  in  nearly  all  trades,  an  inevi- 
table incident  in  the  life  of  even  the  most  competent  and  the 
best  conducted  workman.  To  diminish  the  frequency  and 
duration  of  these  times  of  enforced  idleness,  to  mitigate  the 
hardships  that  they  cause,  and  to  prevent  them  from  producing 
permanent  degradation  of  personal  character  is,  as  we  have 
seen,  one  of  the  foremost  objects  of  Trade  Unionism.1  But 
this  evil,  arising  mainly  from  the  seasonal  or  cyclical  fluctua- 
tions in  the  volume  of  employment  for  the  competent,  has 
no  relation  to  the  problem  of  how  to  deal  with  the  incom- 
petent. So  long  as  these  two  problems  are  hopelessly 
entangled  with  each  other,  and  habitually  regarded  as  one 
and  the  same  thing,  any  scientific  treatment  of  either  of 
them  is  impossible. 

The  problem  of  the  Unemployable  is  not  created  by  the 

1  We  recur  to  this  in  our  next  chapter,  "  Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy." 


Economic  Characteristics  785 

fixing  of  a  National  Minimum  by  law.  The  Unemployable 
we  have  always  with  us.  With  regard  to  certain  sections  of 
the  population,  this  unemployment  is  not  a  mark  of  social 
disease,  but  actually  of  social  health.  From  the  standpoint 
of  national  efficiency,  no  less  than  from  that  of  humanity,  it 
is  desirable  that  the  children,  the  aged,  and  the  child-bearing 
women  should  not  be  compelled  by  their  necessities  to  earn 
their  own  maintenance  in  the  labor  market.  But  in  all 
other  cases,  incapacity  or  refusal  to  produce  a  livelihood  is  a 
symptom  of  ill-health  or  disease,  physical  or  mental.  With 
regard  to  the  principal  classes  of  these  Unemployable — the 
sick  and  the  crippled,  the  idiots  and  lunatics,  the  epileptic, 
the  blind  and  the  deaf  and  dumb,  the  criminals  and  the 
incorrigibly  idle,  and  all  who  are  actually  "  morally  deficient " 
— the  incapacity  is  the  result  of  individual  disease  from 
which  no  society  can  expect  to  be  completely  free.  But 
we  have  a  third  section  of  the  Unemployable,  men  and 
women  who,  without  suffering  from  apparent  disease  of  body 
or  mind,  are  incapable  of  steady  or  continuous  application, 
or  who  are  so  deficient  in  strength,  speed,  or  skill  that  they 
are  incapable,  in  the  industrial  order  in  which  they  find 
themselves,  of  producing  their  maintenance  at  any  occupation 
whatsoever.  The  two  latter  sections — the  physically  or 
mentally  diseased  and  the  constitutionally  inefficient — may, 
in  all  their  several  subdivisions,  either  be  increased  or  dimin- 
ished in  numbers  according  to  the  wisdom  of  our  social 
arrangements.  If  we  desire  to  reduce  these  Unemployable 
to  a  minimum,  it  is  necessary,  as  regards  each  of  the  sub- 
sections, to  pursue  a  twofold  policy.  We  must,  on  the  one 
hand,  arrange  our  social  organisation  in  such  a  way  that  the 
smallest  possible  amount  of  such  degeneracy,  whether  physical 
or  mental,  is  produced.  We  must,  on  the  other  hand,  treat 
the  cases  that  are  produced  in  such  a  way  as  to  arrest  the 
progress  of  the  malady,  and  as  far  as  possible  restore  the 
patient  to  health.1 

1  As  regards  bodily  disease,   this  twofold  policy  is  now   prescribed  by   the 
Public  Health  Acts.     To  maintain  a  high  standard  of  health,  "  common  rules" 
VOL.  II  3  E 


786  Trade  Union  Theory 

Now,  we  cannot  here  enter  into  the  appropriate  social 
regimen  and  curative  treatment  best  calculated  to  minimise 
the  production  of  the  Unemployable  in  each  subdivision,  and 
to  expedite  the  recovery  of  such  as  are  produced.  These 
physical  and  moral  weaklings  and  degenerates  must  somehow 
be  maintained  at  the  expense  of  other  persons.  They  may  be 
provided  for  from  their  own  property  or  savings,  by  charity 
or  from  public  funds,  with  or  without  being  set  to  work  in 
whatever  ways  are  within  their  capacity.  But  of  all  ways  of 
dealing  with  these  unfortunate  parasites  the  most  ruinous  to 
the  community  is  to  allow  them  unrestrainedly  to  compete 
as  wage-earners  for  situations  in  the  industrial  organisation. 
For  this  at  once  prevents  competition  from  resulting  in  the 
Selection  of  the  Most  Fit,  and  thus  defeats  its  very  object.1 
In  the  absence  of  any  Common  Rule,  it  will,  as  we  have 
seen,  often  pay  an  employer  to  select  a  physical  or  moral 
invalid,  who  offers  his  services  for  a  parasitic  wage,  rather 
than  the  most  efficient  workman,  who  stands  out  for  the 
conditions  necessary  for  the  maintenance  of  his  efficiency. 
In  the  same  way,  a  whole  industry  may  batten  on  parasitic 
labor,  diverting  the  nation's  capital  and  brains  from  more 
productive  processes,  and  undermining  the  position  of  its 
more  capable  artisans.  And  where  the  industrial  parasitism 
takes  the  form  of  irregular  employment — as,  for  instance, 
among  the  outworkers  in  all  great  cities  and  the  London 
dock-laborers — its  effect  is  actually  to  extend  the  area  of  the 
disease.  The  sum  of  employment  given  would  suffice  to 
keep  in  regular  work,  at  something  like  adequate  weekly 
earnings,  a  certain  proportion  of  these  casual  workers.  But 
because  it  is  distributed,  as  partial  employment  and  partial 
maintenance,  among  the  entire  class,  its  insufficiency  and 
irregularity  demoralise  all  alike,  and  render  whole  sections 

as  to  drainage  and  water-supply,  nuisances,  and  overcrowding  are  enforced  on 
every  one.  To  deal  with  such  disease  as  nevertheless  occurs,  hospitals  are 
provided.  And  when  it  is  supposed  that  the  sick  contaminate  those  who  are 
well,  isolation  and  proper  treatment  are  compulsory. 

1   "The  main  function  of  competition  is  that  of  selection." — Professor  Fox- 
well  (in  the  essay  cited  on  p.  689). 


Economic  Characteristics  787 

of  the  population  of  our  large  cities  permanently  incapable  of 
regular  conduct  and  continuous  work.  Thus,  the  disease 
perpetuates  itself,  and  becomes,  by  its  very  vastness,  incapable 
of  being  isolated  and  properly  treated.  A  dim  appreciation 
of  the  evil  effects  of  any  mixing  of  degenerates  in  daily  life, 
joined,  of  course,  with  motives  of  humanity,  has  caused  the 
sick  and  the  infirm,  the  imbeciles  and  the  lunatics,  even  the 
cripples  and  the  epileptics,  to  be,  in  all  civilised  communities, 
increasingly  removed  off  the  competitive  labor  market,  and 
scientifically  dealt  with  according  to  their  capacities  and 
their  needs.  The  "  Labor  Colonies "  of  Holland  and  Ger- 
many are,  from  this  point  of  view,  an  extension  of  the  same 
policy.  To  maintain  our  industrial  invalids,  even  in  idleness, 
from  public  funds,  involves  a  definite  and  known  burden  on 
the  community.  To  allow  them  to  remain  at  large,  in 
parasitic  competition  with  those  who  are  whole,  is  to  con- 
taminate the  labor  market,  and  means  a  disastrous  lowering 
of  the  Standard  of  Life  and  Standard  of  Conduct,  not  for 
them  alone,  but  for  the  entire  wage-earning  class.1 

Thus,  in  our  opinion,  the  adoption  of  the  Policy  of 
a  National  Minimum  of  education,  sanitation,  leisure,  and 
wages  would  in  no  way  increase  the  amount  of  maintenance 
which  has  to  be  provided  by  the  community  in  one  form  or 
another,  for  persons  incapable  of  producing  their  own  keep.  It 
would,  on  the  contrary,  tend  steadily  to  reduce  it,  both  by 
diminishing  the  number  of  weaklings  or  degenerates  annually 
produced,  and  by  definitely  marking  out  such  as  exist,  so 
that  they  could  be  isolated  and  properly  treated.2 

1  If  the  wages  of  every  class  of  labor,  under  perfect  competition,  tend  to  be 
no  more  than  the  net  produce  due  to  the  additional  labor  of  the  marginal  laborer 
of  that  class,  who  is  on  the  verge  of  not  being  employed  at  all,  the  abstraction  of 
the  paupers,  not  necessarily  from  productive  labor  for  themselves  but  from  the 
competitive  labor  market,  by  raising  the  capacity  of  the  marginal  wage-laborer, 
would  seem  to  increase  the  wages  of  the  entire  laboring  class. 

2  The  persons  withdrawn  from  the  competitive  labor  market,    whether  as 
invalids  or  aged,  paupers  or  criminals,  need  not  necessarily  be  idle.      It  would, 
on   the  contrary,  usually  be  for  their  own  good,  as  well  as  for  the  pecuniary 
interest  of  the  community,  that  they  should  do  such  work  as  they  are  capable  of. 
But  it  is  of  vital  importance  that  their  products  should  not  be  sold  in  the  open 
market.      If  their  products  are  sold,  they  must  inevitably  undercut  the   wares 


788  Trade  Union  Theory 

The  exact  point  at  which  the  National  Minimum  should  be 
fixed  will,  however,  always  be  a  matter  of  keen  discussion. 
It  will  clearly  be  to  the  direct  advantage  of  the  wage-earning 
class,  and  especially  to  the  large  majority  of  self-supporting 
but  comparatively  unskilled  adult  laborers,  that  the  National 
Minimum  should  be  fixed  as  high  as  possible,  as  this  will 
ensure  to  them  a  good  wage.  Moreover,  every  trade 
momentarily  hard  pressed  by  foreign  competition,  whether 
by  way  of  import  or  of  export  trade,  will  see  an  advantage  to 
itself  in  raising  the  Standard  of  Life  of  those  who  are  in- 
directly its  rivals.  Even  those  employers  who  are  already 
paying  more  than  the  minimum  will  be  drawn  by  their 
economic  interests  in  this  direction.  On  the  other  hand,  the 
employers  in  trades  using  low-paid  labor  would  resent  the 
dislocation  to  which  a  compulsory  raising  of  conditions  would 
subject  them,  and  they  would  find  powerful  allies  in  the 
whole  body  of  taxpayers,  alarmed  at  the  prospect  of  having 

made  by  self-supporting  operatives,  who  will  therefore  find  their  employment 
rendered  less  continuous  than  it  would  otherwise  be,  and  wJio  will  accordingly  be 
unable  to  resist  the  reductions  forced  upon  them  by  their  employers.  This  is  not, 
as  is  often  argued,  because  the  institution  laborers  displace  other  operatives,  but 
because  they  lower  the  price  of  the  product.  The  psychological  effect  on  the 
market  is  even  more  serious  than  the  direct  displacement  of  custom.  Every 
private  manufacturer  fears  that  he  may  be  the  one  destined  to  lose  his  customers 
to  the  institution  which  need  not  consider  cost  of  production  at  all ;  and  this  fear 
supplies  the  buyers  with  an  irresistible  lever  for  forcing  down  price.  The  harm 
lies  in  this  lowering  of  the  Standard  of  Life  of  other  classes,  not  in  any  mere 
diversion  from  them  of  possible  additional  custom.  Hence  there  is  no  economic 
harm,  and  nothing  but  gain,  in  the  inmates  of  institutions  producing  for  consumption 
or  use  inside  the  institution.  This  has  no  tendency  to  lower  prices  or  wages  out- 
side, any  more  than  the  fact  that  sailors  at  sea  wash  their  own  clothes  lowers  the 
wages  of  laundresses  on  land.  And  there  would  be  no  economic  harm  in  the 
supported  workers  performing  the  whole  of  some,  new  service  for  the  community, 
if  this  was  within  their  capacity,  and  if  it  paid  better  to  keep  all  the  more 
efficient  workers  employed  in  other  ways.  The  same  would  be  the  case  if  the 
service  were  not  new,  and  if  it  were,  with  due  consideration  for  existing  workers, 
wholly  taken  out  of  the  domain  of  competitive  industry.  Thus  the  time  might 
arrive  when  all  efficient  Englishmen  would  be  able  to  employ  their  brains  and 
labor  to  greater  advantage  than  in  growing  cereals  and  breeding  stock  ;  and  the 
main  processes  of  agriculture  might  become,  perhaps  in  conjunction  with  muni- 
cipal sewage-farms,  abattoirs,  and  dairies,  exclusively  Poor  Law  occupations,  pro- 
ducing not  for  profit  but  for  the  sake  of  providing  healthful  occupation  for  the 
paupers,  the  infirm,  and  the  aged,  and  selling  their  produce  in  competition  only 
with  foreign  imports  at  the  prices  determined  by  these. 


Economic  Characteristics  789 

to  maintain  in  public  institutions  an  enlarged  residuum  of 
the  Unemployable.  The  economist  would  be  disinclined  to 
give  much  weight  to  any  of  these  arguments,  and  would 
rather  press  upon  the  statesman  the  paramount  necessity  of 
so  fixing  and  gradually  raising  the  National  Minimum  as 
progressively  to  increase  the  efficiency  of  the  community  as 
a  whole,  without  casting  an  undue  burden  on  the  present 
generation  of  taxpayers. 


(g)  Summary  of  the  Economic  Characteristics  of  the 
Device  of  the  Common  Rule 

The  preceding  analysis  of  the  economic  effects  of  the 
Device  of  the  Common  Rule,  first  as  practised  by  isolated 
and  separate  trades,  then  as  limited  by  the  substitution  of 
alternative  processes  or  alternative  products,  at  home  or 
abroad  ;  and  finally  extended,  by  way  of  check  on  the  illegi- 
timate use  of  this  substitution,  from  particular  trades  to  the 
community  as  a  whole,  will  have  revealed  to  the  student  the 
conditions  under  which  each  trade,  and  the  whole  body  of 
wage-earners,  will  obtain  the  best  conditions  of  employment 
then  and  there  practicable,  and  at  the  same  time  the  manner 
in  which  the  utmost  possible  efficiency  of  the  nation's  industry 
will  be  secured. 

We  see,  to  begin  with,  that  the  need  for  the  Common 
Rule  is  greatest  at  the  very  base  of  the  social  pyramid.1 
The  first  necessity  for  obtaining  the  greatest  possible  effi- 
ciency of  the  community  as  a  whole,  is  so  to  control  the 
struggle  for  existence  that  no  section  is  pushed  by  it  into 
parasitism  or  degeneration.  In  the  interests  of  the  eco- 
nomically independent  sections  of  wage-earners,  whose  labor 

1  On  the  social  importance  of  not  abandoning  to  themselves  those  weakest 
classes  of  wage-earners  who  are  unable  to  form  strong  combinations,  see  Dr. 
Heinrich  Herkner's  Die  Sociale  Reform  ah  Gebot  des  Wirtschaftlichen  Fortschrittes 
(Leipzig,  1891),  ch.  x.  ;  and  the  reports  entitled  Arbeitscinstellungen  und  Fort~ 
bildung  des  Arbeitcrvertrages  (Leipzig,  1890),  pp.  12,  35,  etc. 


790  Trade  Union  Theory 

might  be  displaced  by  a  parasitic  class  of  workers,  no  less 
than  in  the  interests  of  the  whole  community  of  citizens, 
threatened  with  the  growth  of  degenerate  or  dependent 
classes,  it  is  vitally  important  to  construct  a  solid  basis  for 
the  industrial  pyramid,  below  which  no  section  of  wage- 
earners,  however  great  the  pressure,  can  ever  be  forced. 
Such  an  extension  of  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule  from 
the  trade  to  the  whole  nation — the  enforcement  of  National 
Minimum  conditions  as  to  sanitation  and  safety,  leisure  and 
wages,  below  which  no  industry  should  be  allowed  to  be 
carried  on — would,  we  may  infer,  have  the  same  economic 
effect  on  the  industry  of  the  community  as  the  introduction 
of  the  Common  Rule  has  on  each  particular  trade.  Thus  it 
would  in  no  way  prevent  competition  between  trades,  or 
lessen  its  intensity.  The  consumer  would  be  free  to  select 
whatever  product  he  preferred,  whether  it  was  made  by  men 
or  by  women,  by  hand  or  by  machinery,  by  his  own  country- 
men or  by  foreigners.  The  capitalist  would  be  free  to 
introduce  any  machinery,  to  use  any  process,  or  to  employ 
any  class  of  labor  that  he  thought  most  profitable  to  himself. 
The  operative,  whether  man  or  woman,  would  be  free  to 
enter  any  trade,  or  to  change  from  one  trade  to  another,  as 
he  or  she  might  be  disposed.  All  that  the  community  would 
require  would  be  that  there  should  be  no  parasitic  labor ; 
that  is  to  say,  that  no  employer  should  be  allowed  to  offer, 
and  no  operative  should  be  permitted  to  accept,  employment 
under  conditions  below  the  minimum  which  the  community 
had  decided  to  be  necessary  to  keep  the  lowest  class  in  full 
and  continued  efficiency  as  producers  and  citizens.  Under 
these  circumstances  the  pressure  of  competition  would  be 
shifted  from  wages  to  quality.  Alike  between  classes,  pro- 
cesses, and  products,  a  genuine  Selection  of  the  Fittest,  un- 
handicapped  by  any  bounty,  would  have  free  play.  If  one 
class  of  operatives  superseded  another  class,  it  would  be 
because  the  successful  workers  could  perform  the  service 
positively  better  than  their  rivals,  whilst  themselves  accepting 
no  subsidy  and  suffering  no  deterioration.  The  result  would 


Economic  Characteristics  791 

be  that,  the  necessary  conditions  of  health  being  secured,  the 
struggle  for  existence  would  take  the  form  of  progressive 
Functional  Adaptation  to  a  higher  level,  each  class  seeking  to 
maintain  its  position  by  improving  its  technical  capacity.1 

This  National  Minimum  of  conditions  for  the  most  help- 
less and  dependent  grades  of  labor  can,  it  is  obvious,  be 
obtained  only  by  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment,  and  it 
will  represent,  not  the  ideal  condition  which  each  section 
strives  to  attain  for  itself,  but  what  the  bulk  of  better-off 
citizens  are  willing  to  concede  to  a  minority  of  less  fortunate 
persons  in  order  to  avoid  the  financial  burden  and  social 
contamination  involved  in  the  growth  of  parasitic  or 
degenerate  classes.  But  if  the  maximum  income  for  the 
workers  in  each  trade,  and  also  the  maximum  efficiency  of 
the  whole  industrial  machine  is  to  be  secured,  no  section 
will  remain  satisfied  with  these  minimum  conditions.  The 
greatest  possible  progress  will  be  obtained  by  each  grade  of 
labor  organising  itself,  and  perpetually  pushing  upwards — 
seeking  by  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule  to  divert,  within 
each  occupation,  the  whole  force  of  competition  from  wages 
to  quality,  from  remuneration  to  service,  so  as  to  secure  always 
the  selection  for  employment  of  those  individuals  who  have 
the  most  developed  faculties,  rather  than  those  who  have  the 

1  To  give  only  two  out  of  many  instances,  we  can  imagine  nothing  more 
calculated  to  improve  the  social  position  of  women,  and  to  render  them 
economically  independent  of  their  sexual  relationship,  than  the  gradual  introduc- 
tion of  a  legal  minimum  wage,  below  which  their  employment  should  not  be  per- 
mitted. Nothing  does  so  much  at  present  to  prevent  women  becoming  technically 
proficient  in  industry,  and  to  deprive  girls  of  incentive  to  acquire  technical  educa- 
tion, than  their  feeling  that  they  can  obtain  employment  as  they  are,  if  only  they 
will  accept  low  enough  wages  !  The  result  of  the  low  wages  is  a  deplorably  low 
standard  of  efficiency,  due  to  lack  alike  of  proper  physiological  conditions  and  of 
stimulus  to  greater  exertions.  The  improvement  in  the  capacity  and  technical 
efficiency  of  women  teachers  in  the  last  twenty  years,  concurrently  with  the 
introduction  of  fixed  standards  of  qualification  by  the  Education  Department  and, 
to  some  extent,  the  adoption  by  School  Boards  of  full  subsistence  wages,  is 
especially  significant  in  this  connection.  The  other  instance  is  that  of  the  casual 
unskilled  laborer  of  the  great  cities.  At  present  he  knows  that  he  can  earn  his 
miserable  pittance  by  transient  employment,  without  a  character,  without  regu- 
larity of  attendance  day  by  day,  and  without  technical  skill.  A  legal  minimum 
weekly  wage  would  induce  the  employers  to  pick  their  men,  and  at  once  set  up  a 
Selection  of  the  Fittest  for  regularity,  trustworthiness,  and  skill. 


792  Trade  Union  Theory 

fewest  needs.  The  object  of  each  section  will  be  to  raise  its 
own  service  to  the  highest  possible  degree  of  specialised 
excellency,  and  to  differentiate  itself  to  the  utmost  from  the 
unspecialised  and  "  unskilled "  labor,  commanding  only  the 
National  Minimum.  In  this  way,  each  body  of  specialists 
becomes  able  to  insist  on  its  own  "  rent  of  ability  "  or  "  rent  of 
opportunity."  The  more  open  the  occupation  is  to  newcomers, 
and  the  more  attractive  are  the  conditions  that  are  obtained  by 
those  who  are  already  employed,  the  more  effective  will  become 
the  constant  Selection  of  the  Fittest.  The  more  progressive 
is  the  industry  and  the  more  opportunities  it  provides  for 
technical  instruction,  the  greater  will  be  the  Functional  Adapt- 
ation to  a  higher  level.  And  so  long  as  this  progressive 
raising  of  the  Common  Rule  brings  with  it,  either  through 
Functional  Adaptation  or  the  Selection  of  the  Fittest,  an 
equivalent  increase  in  the  operatives'  own  productive  efficiency, 
the  added  wages,  or  other  improvement  of  conditions,  will  in 
themselves  constitute  a  clear  addition  to  the  income  of  the 
community.  And  in  so  far  as  the  maintenance  of  the  Com- 
mon Rule  brings  pressure  to  bear  on  the  brains  of  the 
employers,  so  as  to  compel  them  to  improve  the  technical 
processes  of  the  trade ;  and  in  so  far  as  the  progressive 
raising  of  the  standard  concentrates  industry  in  the  hands  of 
the  most  capable  employers,  in  the  best-equipped  establish- 
ments, in  the  most  advantageous  sites,  the  organised  wage- 
earners,  in  seeking  to  improve  their  own  conditions,  will 
incidentally  have  positively  added  to  the  resources  of  the 
other  classes  of  the  community  as  well  as  to  their  own.  So 
far  the  improvement  in  the  wage-earners'  condition  need  not 
lead  to  any  rise  in  the  price  of  commodities.  When, 
however,  the  operatives  in  any  given  industry  have  ex- 
hausted the  increased  efficiency  due  to  Functional  Adapt- 
ation and  the  Selection  of  the  Fittest,  whether  acting  on  the 
employers  or  on  workmen,  any  further  advance  of  wages 
will,  unless  under  very  exceptional  conditions,  result  in  a 
slackening  of  the  demand  for  their  product.  The  same 
result  happens  in  the  more  frequent  case  of  the  advance  in 


Economic  Characteristics  793 

wages  outstripping  for  a  time  the  increase  in  efficiency,  or 
again,  even  without  a  rise  of  wages  or  of  prices,  a  change 
of  fashion  or  a  new  invention  may  cause  the  substitution  of 
another  grade  of  labor.  In  all  these  cases,  the  progress  of 
the  advance  movement  of  a  particular  trade  will  be  effectively 
stopped  by  an  increase  in  the  proportion  of  its  unemployed 
members.  This,  indeed,  marks  the  limit  of  the  possible 
advance  in  the  conditions  of  any  particular  trade,  beyond 
which  the  progressive  raising  of  the  Common  Rule,  whether 
by  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining  or  by  that  of  Legal 
Enactment,  fails  to  achieve  its  object.  Against  a  positive 
slackening  of  the  consumers'  demand,  the  producers  have  no 
remedy.  If,  indeed,  the  wages  and  other  conditions  pre- 
viously enjoyed  have  been  unnecessarily  good — if,  that  is  to 
say,  they  have  been  more  than  enough  to  maintain  the 
particular  degree  of  specialised  intensity  of  the  trade  in 
question — it  might  theoretically  pay  the  Trade  Union  to 
submit  to  a  reduction.  In  our  opinion,  this  is  seldom  the 
case  in  practice.  Even  in  the  relatively  well-paid  trades,  in 
times  of  comparative  prosperity,  the  ordinary  income  of  a 
skilled  mechanic — in  England,  from  £80  to  £150  per  annum 
— is  below  the  amount  necessary  for  the  development  in 
himself,  his  wife,  and  his  children  of  the  highest  efficiency 
that  they  are  capable  of.  If  the  consumers'  demand  is 
falling  off,  and  is  being  diverted  to  some  other  process  or 
some  other  product,  the  decline  can  seldom  be  arrested  by 
any  slight  fall  in  price,  and  the  Trade  Union  may  well  think 
that  the  comparatively  small  saving  in  the  total  cost  of  pro- 
duction which  would  be  caused  by  even  a  10  or  20  per  cent 
decline  of  wages,  would  probably  be  quite  illusory.1  On  the 

1  When  the  slackening  of  demand  for  a  particular  trade  is  not  caused  by  any 
substitution,  but  is  the  result  merely  of  a  universal  contraction  of  the  world's 
industry — due,  for  instance,  to  a  general  failure  of  crops — there  would  be  no 
advantage  in  a  reduction  of  wages,  either  in  a  particular  trade,  or  generally  of 
the  wage-earners  of  the  world.  As  any  such  reduction  could  not  possibly  increase 
the  aggregate  demand  (which  is  the  aggregate  product),  it  would  serve  no  other 
purpose  than  to  make  up,  to  the  capitalists  of  the  world,  part  of  the  diminution 
of  income  that  they  would  otherwise  suffer.  Rather  than  submit  to  a  lowering 
of  the  standard  conditions  of  employment  it  would  be  better,  in  such  a  case, 


794  Trade  Union  Theory 

other  hand,  there  is,  as  we  have  shown  in  our  chapter  on  "  New 
Processes  and  Machinery,"  no  policy  so  disastrous  for  the 
skilled  operatives  to  pursue  as  to  submit  to  any  reduction  of 
wages,  any  lengthening  of  hours,  or  any  worsening  of  sanitary 
conditions,  that  in  any  way  impairs  their  peculiar  specialist 
efficiency.  In  the  interests  of  the  community  as  a  whole, 
no  less  than  of  their  own  trade,  such  of  their  members  as 
remain  in  employment  must  at  all  hazards  maintain  un- 
diminished  the  high  standard  of  life  which  alone  has  per- 
mitted them  to  evolve  their  exceptional  talent.  What  a 
Trade  Union  can  do,  if  it  finds  the  demand  for  its  members' 
services  steadily  falling  off,  is  to  set  its  expert  officials  to 
discover  the  exact  cause  of  this  change  of  demand.  If  the 
decline  is  not  due  to  a  merely  temporary  depression  of  trade 
in  general  ;  if,  that  is  to  say,  there  is  going  on  an  actual 
substitution  of  process  or  product  which  is  likely  to  continue, 
the  first  duty  of  the  Trade  Union  is  to  make  the  fact  widely 
known  to  its  own  members  and  the  public,  so  that  members 
may  seize  every  opportunity  of  escaping  from  the  trade,  and 
so  that  parents  may  learn  to  avoid  putting  their  sons  to  so 
unpromising  an  occupation.  The  second  duty  of  the 
threatened  trade  is  to  look  sharply  into  the  conditions  under 
which  the  substituted  article  is  being  produced,  or  (in  the 
case  of  foreign  competition)  into  the  conditions  of  all  the 
export  trades  of  the  country.  It  may  be  that  these  are 
escaping  regulation  altogether,  or  that  there  is  a  case  for 
demanding  a  rise  in  the  legal  minimum  of  conditions  of 
employment.  The  best  policy  of  the  threatened  trade  is, 
therefore,  to  throw  itself  vigorously  into  the  agitation  for  a 
general  levelling  up  of  the  National  Minimum.  And  in  this 
policy  they  will  find  themselves  increasingly  supported  by 

for  the  workers  of  each  community  to  maintain  their  rate  unimpaired,  and 
subsidise  their  unemployed  members.  The  frequent  result  of  unregulated 
competition  in  times  of  general  depression  of  trade — that  the  hours  of  labor  of 
the  workers  in  employment  are  positively  lengthened  because  of  their  strategic 
weakness,  and  the  numbers  unemployed  thereby  unnecessarily  increased — is  an 
arrangement  so  insane  that  it  would  not  be  tolerated  but  for  the  superstition 
that  the  anarchy  of  "  Nature  "  was  somehow  superior  to  the  deliberate  adjust- 
ments of  science. 


Economic  Characteristics  795 

public  opinion.  For  if  all  the  occupations  enjoying  any 
organisation  at  all  have  been  pursuing  the  policy  of  pushing 
up  their  Common  Rules  and  developing  their  own  specialisa- 
tion, there  will  have  been  set  up,  in  the  community  as  a 
whole,  a  new  conception  of  what  is  necessary  for  the  decent 
existence  of  any  class  of  workers.  In  each  trade,  as  we  have 
seen,  the  enforcement  of  a  Common  Rule  automatically  sets 
up  a  new  "  mean  "  for  the  trade,  which  tends  to  become  a 
new  minimum.  Similarly,  when  a  National  Minimum  has 
been  effectively  enforced ;  and  when  one  occupation  after 
another  has  raised  itself  above  that  minimum  to  the  extent 
of  its  particular  skill,  there  will  have  been  created,  in  the 
public  opinion  both  of  the  wage-earners  and  other  classes, 
not  excluding  even  the  employers,  a  new  standard  of 
expenditure  for  the  average  working-class  family.  The 
psychological  establishment  of  this  new  standard  makes  the 
old  minimum,  once  considered  a  boon,  appear  "starvation 
wages."  Hence  a  growing  discontent  among  the  poorest 
classes  of  workers,  and  rising  sympathy  for  their  privations, 
will  lead  eventually  to  a  rise  in  the  minimum.  This  rise  will 
be  justified  to  the  economists  by  the  increase  in  efficiency 
which  the  enforcement  of  the  legal  minimum  will  have 
brought  about.  Thus,  the  whole  community  of  wage-earners, 
including  the  lowest  sections  of  it,  may  by  a  persistent  and 
systematic  use  of  the  Device  of  the  Common  Rule,  secure 
an  indefinite,  though  of  course  not  an  unlimited,  rise  in  its 
Standard  of  Life.  And  in  this  universal  and  elaborate 
application  of  the  Common  Rule,  the  economist  finds  a  sound 
and  consistent  theory  of  Trade  Unionism,  adapted  to  the 
conditions  of  modern  industry  ;  applicable  to  the  circum- 
stances of  each  particular  trade  ;  acceptable  by  the  whole 
body  of  wage-earners  ;  and  positively  conducive  to  national 
efficiency  and  national  wealth. 


796  Trade  Union  Theory 

(It)  Trade  Union  Methods 

Our  survey  of  the  economic  characteristics  of  Trade 
Unionism  would  not  be  complete  without  some  comparison, 
from  an  economic  standpoint,  of  the  three  Methods  by  which, 
as  we  have  seen,  Trade  Unions  seek  to  attain  their  ends. 
At  first  sight  this  may  seem  unnecessary.  When  once  a 
Trade  Union  Regulation  has  been  successfully  enforced  upon 
the  employers  and  workmen  in  a  trade,  it  can  be  economically 
of  no  consequence  whether  the  Regulation  has  been  obtained 
by  Legal  Enactment,  or  Collective  Bargaining,  or  by  the 
more  silent  but  not  less  coercive  influence  that  may  be 
exerted  by  Mutual  Insurance.  The  owners  of  mining 
royalties,  the  lessees  of  the  coal,  and  the  individual  hewers 
will  find  their  faculties  and  desires  affected  in  exactly  the 
same  way,  whether  the  tonnage-rates  for  the  Northumberland 
coal  mines  are  fixed  by  law  or  by  the  irresistible  fiat  of  the 
Joint  Committee.  It  is  immaterial  to  the  owner  of  an  old- 
fashioned  cotton-mill  whether  the  shortening  of  hours,  or  the 
raising  of  the  minimum  cubic  space  required  by  each  operative, 
which  finally  destroys  his  margin  of  profit,  is  enforced  by  the 
visits  of  the  Factory  Inspector  or  by  those  of  the  secretaries 
of  the  Employers'  and  Operatives'  Associations.  It  might 
be  urged,  in  short,  that  it  is  the  Trade  Union  Regulation 
itself  which  influences  the  organisation  of  industry,  or  alters 
cost  of  production,  profits,  or  price,  not  the  particular  Method 
by  which  the  Regulation  is  secured. 

But  this  is  to  assume  that,  whether  a  Trade  Union 
Regulation  is  supported  by  one  Method  or  the  other,  it  will 
be  obtained  and  enforced  with  equal  friction,  equal  effective- 
ness, equal  universality,  and  equal  rapidity  of  application  to 
the  changing  circumstances.  Thus,  the  general  reduction  of 
the  hours  of  labor,  which  characterised  the  decade  1870  to 
1880,  had  distinctive  economic  results  of  its  own,  whether  it 
was  effected  by  Legal  Enactment  (as  in  the  textile  mills),  or  by 
Collective  Bargaining  (as  in  the  engineering  workshops).  But 
the  economist  cannot  overlook  the  fact  that  the  reduction  was, 


Economic  Characteristics  797 

in  the  one  case,  secured  without  any  cessation  of  industry, 
enforced  universally  on  all  establishments  in  the  trade  from 
one  end  of  the  kingdom  to  the  other,  and  rigidly  maintained 
without  struggle  in  subsequent  years.  In  the  other  case,  the 
reduction  of  hours  cost  the  community  a  five  months'  stop- 
page of  engineering  industry  in  one  of  its  most  important 
centres,  and  many  other  struggles.1  It  never  became  universal, 
even  in  the  same  industry,  and  it  has  not  been  uniformly 
maintained.  On  the  other  hand,  the  Engineers  got  the 
reduction  three  years  sooner  than  the  Cotton  Operatives,  and 
have  been  able,  in  times  of  good  trade,  in  well-organised 
districts,  to  obtain  even  further  reductions.  To  complete  the 
economic  analysis  of  Trade  Unionism,  we  have  therefore  to 
inquire  how  far  these  important  differences  in  the  application 
of  the  Regulations  are  characteristic  of  the  several  Methods 
by  which  they  are  enforced.  In  this  inquiry,  we  may  leave 
out  the  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance,  which,  in  its  economic 
aspect,  is  hardly  distinguishable  from  imperfect  Collective 
Bargaining,  and  which,  except  in  a  few  small  trades,  may  be 
regarded  as  an  adjunct  of  the  other  Methods.2  The  question 
therefore  resolves  itself  into  the  manner  in  which  the 
economic  results  of  the  various  Trade  Union  Regulations 

1  History  of  Trade  Unionism^  pp.  299-302. 

2  This  omits  from  consideration  the  purely  Friendly  Society  side  of  Trade 
Unionism.     The  provision  made  by  wage-earning  families  against  sickness  and 
accident,  and  the  expenses  of  burial,  has  an  important  effect  on  their  well-being, 
and  cannot  be  ignored  by  the  economist.      But  in  this  respect,  as  we  have  seen  in 
our  chapter  on  "  The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance,"  the  Trade  Unions  amount  to  no 
more  than  small  offshoots  from  the  great  Friendly  Society  movement,  and  (as 
regards  death  benefit)  of  the  equally  extensive  system  of  "industrial  insurance." 
In  the  United    Kingdom,   these    provide,   in    the   aggregate,   many  times  more 
sick  and  funeral  benefit  than  the  whole  of  the  Trade  Unions  put  together.     The 
economic  results  of  this  form  of  saving,  like  that  of  mere  individual  hoarding  or 
deposit    in    a   savings    bank,  are,  therefore,   in  no  way  characteristic  of  Trade 
Unionism.       The    Trade   Union,  as  we  have  seen,  is  a  bad  form  of  Friendly 
Society,  and  if  it  had  to  be  considered   exclusively  as   a  Friendly  Society,  its 
total   lack  of  actuarial  basis  and  absence  of  security  would  bring  upon  it  the 
severest  condemnation.     The  main  benefit  provided  by  the  Trade  Union  is,  how- 
ever, not  sick  pay  or  funeral  money,  but  the  Out  of  Work  Donation,  and  this,  as 
we  have  pointed  out,  must  be  regarded,  not  as  an  end  in  itself,  but  as  a  means  of 
maintaining  or  improving  the  members'  conditions  of  employment — as  a  method, 
that  is,  of  supporting  the  Trade  Union  Regulations. 


7 98  Trade  Union  Theory 

are   modified,  according  as  they  are  enforced  by   Collective 
Bargaining  or  Legal  Enactment. 

Confining  ourselves  to  the  circumstances  of  this  country 
at  the  present  time,  we  see  that  to  obtain  and  enforce  a 
Trade  Union  Regulation  by  the  Method  of  Collective 
Bargaining  necessarily  involves,  as  we  described  in  a  previous 
chapter,  the  drawback  of  occasional  disputes  and  stoppages 
of  work.  The  seven  hundred  or  more  strikes  and  lock-outs 
annually  reported  to  the  Board  of  Trade1  represent  a  con- 
siderable amount  of  economic  friction.  The  laying  idle  of 
costly  and  perishable  machinery  and  plant,  the  dislocation  of 
business  enterprise,  the  diversion  of  orders  to  other  countries, 
the  absorption  in  angry  quarrels  of  the  intellects  which  would 
otherwise  be  devoted  to  the  further  development  of  'our 
industry — above  all,  the  reduction  to  poverty  and  semi- 
starvation  of  thousands  of  workmen — involve  a  serious 
inroad  upon  the  nation's  wealth.  This  perpetual  liability 
to  a  disagreement  between  the  parties  to  a  bargain  is  a 
necessary  accompaniment  of  freedom  of  contract.  We  have 
already  pointed  out  that  if  it  is  thought  desirable  that  the 
parties  to  a  bargain  should  be  free  to  agree  or  not  to  agree, 
it  is  inevitable  that,  human  nature  being  as  it  is,  there  should 
now  and  again  come  a  deadlock,  leading  to  that  trial  of 
strength  which  lies  behind  all  negotiations  between  free  and 
independent  contracting  parties.  The  Trade  Union  Method 
of  Collective  Bargaining,  though  by  its  machinery  for  industrial 
diplomacy  it  may  reduce  to  a  minimum  the  occasions  of 
industrial  war,  can  never,  as  we  have  seen,  altogether  prevent 
its  occurrence.  We  need  not  dwell  any  further  upon  this 
capital  drawback  of  this  particular  Method  of  industrial 
regulation,  as  it  is  one  on  which  both  public  opinion  and 
economic  authority  are  convinced,  and  of  which,  in  our 
judgment,  they  take  even  an  exaggerated  view. 

1  The  reports  on  the  Strikes  and  Lock-outs  of  the  year,  which  have  been 
annually  published  by  the  Labor  Department  of  the  Board  of  Trade  since  1888, 
and  by  various  American  State  Governments,  afford  a  valuable  picture  of  the 
number  and  variety  of  these  disputes. 


Economic  Characteristics  799 

The  use  by  the  Trade  Unions  of  the  Method  of  Legal 
Enactment  has  the  great  economic  merit  of  avoiding  all  the 
waste  and  friction  that  we  have  been  describing.  Whatever 
may  be  the  result  of  a  new  Factory  Act,  it  is  not  bought  at 
the  cost  of  a  strike  or  a  lock-out.  Even  when  a  new  enact 
ment  is  supremely  distasteful  to  both  employers  and  operatives, 
as  in  the  case  of  the  Truck  Act  of  1 896,  there  is  no  cessation 
or  interruption  of  the  nation's  industry.  All  that  happens  is 
that  employers  and  workmen  importune  their  members  of 
Parliament,  and  go  on  deputations  to  the  Home  Secretary, 
to  beg  for  an  amendment  or  a  repeal  of  the  obnoxious  law. 
The  regulations  themselves,  like  the  clauses  of  the  Truck  Act 
which  are  complained  of,  may  be  irksome,  useless,  or  eco- 
nomically injurious,  but  the  method  by  which  they  have 
been  obtained  and  enforced  has  the  inestimable  merit  of 
peaceful  ness. 

The  case  of  the  Truck  Act  of  1896  supplies  an  instance 
of  a  corresponding  drawback  of  the  Method  of  Legal  Enact- 
ment. An  Act  of  Parliament  is  hard  to  obtain,  and  hard  to 
alter.  It  is  therefore  probable  that  an  industry  has  to  go 
on  for  some  years  without  the  regulation  which  would  be 
economically  advantageous  to  it,  or  to  endure  for  some  time 
an  obsolete  regulation  which  could  advantageously  be  amended. 
This  want  of  elasticity  to  meet  changing  circumstances  is 
specially  noticeable  in  our  legislative  machinery  of  the  present 
day,  when  the  one  central  legislature  is  patently  incapable  of 
coping  with  the  incessant  new  applications  of  law  required 
by  a  complicated  society.  It  would  be  interesting  to  ask 
whether  this  defect  is  inherent  in  the  Method  of  Legal  Enact- 
ment. If  the  principle  of  regulating  the  conditions  of 
employment  were  definitely  adopted  by  Parliament,  there 
does  not  seem  any  impossibility  in  the  rules  themselves  being 
made  and  amended  by  the  fiat — carrying  with  it  the  force  of 
law — of  an  executive  department,  a  local  authority,  or  a  com- 
pulsory arbitration  court  for  the  particular  industry.1  But 

1  The  ordinances  of  the  craft-gilds,  the  by-laws  of  the  mediaeval  town  councils, 
and  the  fixing  of  rates  of  wages  by  the  justices  are  familiar  examples  of  law- 


8oo  Trade  Union  Theory 

though  a  community  which  believed  in  regulating  the  condi- 
tions of  employment  by  law  would  be  able  greatly  to  simplify 
and  develop  its  legislative  machinery,  the  making  and  amend- 
ing of  legally  enforcible  rules  must,  we  believe,  necessarily 
be  a  more  stiff  and  cumbrous  process  than  the  concluding 
or  modifying  a  voluntary  trade  agreement  by  a  joint  com- 
mittee. If,  therefore,  it  be  desirable  that  the  Regulation 
itself,  or  the  stringency  with  which  it  is  interpreted  or  applied, 
should  be  constantly  shifted  upwards  or  downwards,  accord- 
ing to  the  changing  circumstances  of  the  day,  or  the  relative 
positions  of  employers  and  workmen,  the  Method  of  Collective 
Bargaining  has  undoubtedly  a  great  advantage  over  the 
Method  of  Legal  Enactment. 

So  far,  therefore,  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  is 
superior  in  the  characteristics  of  peacefulness  and  absence 
of  preliminary  friction,  whilst  in  the  qualities  of  elasticity, 
promptness  of  attainment,  and  facility  of  alteration,  the 
Method  of  Collective  Bargaining  holds  the  field.  When  we 
come  to  the  effectiveness  of  the  Regulation — that  is  to  say, 
the  rigidity,  impartiality,  and  universality  with  which  it  is 
applied — the  issue  is  more  open  to  doubt.  In  our  analysis 
of  the  economic  effects  of  the  Common  Rule,  we  have  seen 
how  important  it  is  that  it  should  really  be  co-extensive  with 
the  industry  in  any  community.  It  will  clearly  make  all  the 
difference  to  the  economic  effect  of  a  reduction  of  hours  or 
an  advance  in  costly  sanitary  comforts,  whether  all  competing 

making,  which,  though  they  were  open  to  many  other  objections,  were  lacking 
neither  in  promptitude  nor  elasticity.  "  The  substance  no  less  than  the  form  of 
the  law  would,  it  is  probable,  be  a  good  deal  improved  if  the  executive  govern- 
ment of  England  could,  like  that  of  France,  by  means  of  decrees,  ordinances,  or 
proclamations  having  the  force  of  law,  work  out  the  detailed  application  of  the 
general  principles  embodied  in  the  Acts  of  the  legislature  "  (A.  V.  Dicey,  The 
Law  of  the  Constitution,  ch.  i. ;  H.  Sidgwick,  Principles  of  Politics,  ch.  xxii.  p. 
433).  Already,  a  large  amount  of  our  legislation  is  made  in  the  form  of  "  rules  " 
or  "  orders  "  by  executive  departments,  sometimes  under  a  general  authority  given 
by  statute,  and  only  nominally  laid  before  Parliament,  sometimes  by  mere 
executive  authority ;  see,  for  instance,  the  eight  volumes  of  Statutory  Rules  and 
Orders  (London,  1897)  in  force  having  the  authority  of  law.  It  is  probable  that 
the  increasing  incapacity  of  the  House  of  Commons  to  cope  with  its  work  will 
lead  to  a  silent  extension  of  this  practice.  We  shall,  in  fact,  be  saved  by  the 
Royal  Prerogative  ! 


Economic  Characteristics  80 1 

employers  are  equally  subjected  to  the  regulation,  or  whether 
this  is  enforced  only  on  particular  establishments  or  particular 
districts.  At  first  sight  it  would  seem  that  this  is  an  over- 
whelming argument  in  favor  of  the  law.  In  our  own  country 
at  the  present  day  factory  legislation  applies  uniformly  from 
one  end  of  the  kingdom  to  another.  If  it  is  properly  drafted 
and  really  intended  to  work,  it  will  be  conscientiously  and 
impartially  enforced  by  the  Home  Office.  But  unfortunately, 
though  the  machinery  for  enforcing  the  regulations  is,  in  the 
United  Kingdom,  exceptionally  efficient,  the  regulations 
themselves  are  still  very  imperfect.  Outside  the  textile  and 
mining  industries,  it  is  not  too  much  to  say  that  they  have 
generally  been  drafted  or  emasculated  by  ministers  or 
legislators  yielding  to  popular  pressure,  but  themselves 
opposed,  in  principle,  to  any  interference  with  the  employer's 
"  freedom  of  enterprise."  Our  Labor  Code  contains  many 
"  bogus  "  clauses,  which  were,  by  their  authors,  never  intended 
to  be  applied,  and  which  the  most  zealous  Factory  Inspectors 
are  unable  to  enforce.  On  the  other  hand,  the  regulations 
which  are  secured  in  Collective  Bargaining  by  the  shrewd  and 
experienced  officials  of  a  powerful  Trade  Union,  are,  from  the 
outset,  intended  to  work,  and,  when  the  trade  is  completely 
organised,  they  are  enforced  with  an  unrelenting  and  detailed 
exactitude  unknown  to  the  Factory  Inspector  or  the  magis- 
trate's court.  But  whereas  the  law,  however  imperfect, 
applies  equally  to  all  firms  and  to  all  districts,  it  is  rare, 
as  we  have  seen,  for  a  Trade  Union  to  secure  a  "  National 
Agreement,"  and  still  more  unusual  for  the  whole  trade  to  be 
so  well  organised  as  to  be  able  to  enforce  any  uniform  terms 
upon  all  the  employers.  The  usual  result  is  that,  though 
the  workmen  enforce  their  Regulations  on  "  society  shops  "  in 
"  good  "  Trade  Union  towns  with  more  than  the  severity  of 
the  law  of  the  land,  there  are  numerous  establishments,  and 
sometimes  whole  districts,  over  which  the  Trade  Union  has 
absolutely  no  control. 

Finally  we  have  the   question — to  the  statesman,  as  we 
have  seen,  of  vital  importance — whether  one  or  other  Method 
VOL.  II  3  F 


802  Trade  Union  Theory 

is  best  calculated  to  prevent  industrial  parasitism.  From  the 
point  of  view  of  the  community,  it  is  essential  that  every 
industry  should  afford,  to  every  person  employed,  at  least 
the  National  Minimum  of  sanitation  and  safety,  leisure  and 
wages,  in  order  to  prevent  any  particular  trade  from  get- 
ting a  virtual  "  bounty "  from  the  community,  in  the  form 
either  of  partially  supported  labor,  or  of  successive  relays  of 
workers  deteriorated  in  their  use.  Only  under  these  condi- 
tions, as  we  have  seen,  has  the  nation  any  assurance  that  its 
industry  will  flow  into  those  channels  in  which  its  capital, 
brains,  and  manual  labor  will  be  applied  to  the  greatest 
economic  advantage,  and  produce  the  greatest  "  National 
Dividend."  Now,  it  is  an  inherent  defect  of  any  sectional 
action  by  particular  Trade  Unions  that  its  success  will 
depend,  not  on  the  real  necessities  of  the  workers,  but  on 
their  strategic  position.  Under  the  Method  of  Collective 
Bargaining  the  provisions  for  Sanitation  and  Safety  would 
differ  from  trade  to  trade,  not  according  to  the  unhealthiness 
or  danger  of  the  process,  but  according  to  the  capacity  of 
the  workers  for  organisation,  the  ability  of  their  leaders,  the 
magnitude  of  their  "  war-chests,"  the  relative  scarcity  of  their 
labor,  and  the  "  squeezability  "  of  their  employers.  Where 
the  hours  of  labor  are  not  affected  by  law,  we  find,  in  fact, 
at  the  present  time,  that  they  vary  from  trade  to  trade  with- 
out the  least  reference  to  the  average  strength  of  the 
workers  concerned,  or  the  exhausting  character  of  their 
labors.  The  London  Silverworkers,  the  Birmingham  Flint 
Glass  Makers,  and  the  various  classes  of  building  operatives 
in  the  Metropolis,  enjoy,  for  instance,  practically  an  Eight 
Hours'  Day,  whilst  the  outworking  Sheffield  Cutlers,  the 
London  Carmen,  and  the  great  race  of  Tailors  everywhere 
work  at  least  half  as  long  again  for  a  smaller  remuneration. 
And,  turning  to  the  four  millions  of  women  wage-earners, 
we  come  to  the  paradoxical  result  that,  wherever  unregulated 
by  law,  the  physically  weakest  class  in  the  world  of  labor  is 
forced  to  work  the  longest  hours  for  the  least  adequate  sub- 
sistence. It  is  clear  that  the  National  Minimum,  whether 


Economic  Characteristics  803 

with  regard  to  sanitation  or  safety,  leisure  or  wages,  cannot 
be  secured,  in  the  cases  in  which  it  is  most  required,  other- 
wise than  by  law.1 

We  see,  therefore,  that  if,  for  the  moment,  we  leave  out 
of  account  the  Regulations  themselves,  the  Method  of  Legal 
Enactment  has,  where  it  can  be  employed,  a  considerable 
balance  of  economic  advantages  over  the  Method  of  Collec- 
tive Bargaining.  It  has,  to  begin  with,  the  great  merit  of 
avoiding  all  stoppages  of  industry  and  of  causing  the  mini- 
mum of  economic  friction.  In  our  own  country,  at  any  rate, 
a  Regulation  enforced  by  Legal  Enactment  will  be  more 
uniformly  and  impartially  applied  throughout  an  industry  as 
a  whole  than  is  ever  likely  to  be  the  case  with  a  Regulation 
enforced  by  Collective  Bargaining.  Its  greatest  drawback  is 
the  cumbrousness  of  the  machinery  that  must  be  set  in 
motion,  and  the  consequent  difficulty  in  quickly  adapting 
the  Regulations  to  new  circumstances.  Hence  the  Method 
of  Legal  Enactment  is  best  adapted  for  those  Regulations 
which  are  based  on  permanent  considerations,  such  as  the 
health  and  efficiency  of  the  workers.  The  minimum  require- 
ments of  Sanitation  and  Safety  need  no  sudden  modifications. 
Much  the  same  argument  applies  to  the  fixing  of  the  Normal 
Day  and  even  of  a  minimum  of  wages,  calculated  so  as  to 


1  Even  when  a  Trade  Union  uses  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment  for  its 
own  benefit,  it  usually  secures  advantages  for  weaker  classes.  Thus,  the  adult 
male  cotton-spinners,  in  getting  shorter  hours  and  improved  sanitation  for  them- 
selves, have  secured  identical  conditions  for  the  comparatively  weak  women  ring- 
spinners  of  Lancashire,  and  for  the  practically  unorganised  women  employed  to 
assist  at  mule-spinning  in  the  mills  of  Glasgow.  And  this  uniformity  of  regula- 
tion, initiated  by  the  19,000  male  spinners,  has  not  only  been  extended  to  all 
the  300,000  workers  in  cotton -mills,  whether  spinners,  weavers,  beamers, 
twisters,  or  card-room  hands,  but  also  to  the  200,000  factory  operatives  in  the 
competing  products  of  the  woollen,  linen,  and  silk  trades.  Finally,  whilst  the 
500,000  operatives  in  the  textile  trades  thus  already  work  under  identical  legal 
conditions,  there  is  a  constant  tendency,  in  every  amendment  of  the  Factory 
Acts,  to  approximate  to  this  "  textile  "  standard  the  regulations  applying  to  the 
hours  and  sanitation  of  all  the  other  industries  of  the  country.  In  short,  when 
Parliament  has  to  determine  the  conditions  of  employment,  it  tends  necessarily, 
whatever  the  trade,  to  base  its  action  on  one  and  the  same  common  assumption 
— on  the  necessity  of  securing  to  every  class  of  workers  at  least  the  minimum 
requirements  of  health  and  efficiency. 


804  Trade  Union  Theory 

prevent  any  class  of  workers  from  being  driven  down  below 
the  standard  of  healthy  subsistence.  These  are  all  matters 
of  physiological  science.  The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment 
is,  in  fact,  economically  the  most  advantageous  way  of  en- 
forcing all  Regulations  based  on  the  Doctrine  of  a  Living 
Wage.1 

But  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining  has  also  its 
legitimate  sphere.  In  our  analysis  of  the  economic  charac- 
teristics of  the  Common  Rule,  we  have  pointed  out  how 
essential  it  is,  in  the  interests  of  each  particular  trade,  and 
also  in  those  of  the  community  as  a  whole,  that  no  section 
of  workers  should  remain  content  with  the  National  Minimum 
secured  by  law,  and  that  each  trade  should  be  perpetually 
trying  to  force  up  its  own  Standard  of  Life  so  as  to  stimulate 
to  the  utmost  the  forces  of  Functional  Adaptation  and  the 
Selection  of  the  Fittest  within  the  occupation.  The  several 
sections  of  workers  show  no  backwardness  in  demanding 
all  that  they  can  get,  and  they  often  desire,  as  we  have 
seen,  to  get  the  law  on  their  side.  But  if  the  Doctrine 
of  Vested  Interests  is  abandoned,  there  are  many  reasons 
which  will  prevent  the  use  of  the  Method  of  Legal  Enact- 
ment for  obtaining  what  we  may  call  this  sectional  "  Rent  of 
Ability,"  or  "  Rent  of  Opportunity."  If,  indeed,  the  workers 
in  any  particular  trade  could  prove  to  the  representatives  of 

1  In  support  of  this  view  we  are  glad  to  be  able  to  quote  an  editorial  of  the 
Times  in  the  palmy  days  of  that  great  organ  of  English  public  opinion.  Re- 
ferring to  the  movement  in  favor  of  shortening  the  hours  of  labor  of  shop 
assistants,  its  leading  article  of  the  nth  November  1846  observed:  "Now  we 
would  humbly  suggest  that,  after  all,  an  Act  of  Parliament  would  be  the  most 
short  and  certain  mode  of  effecting  the  proposed  object.  It  would  be  universal 
in  its  operation.  It  would  admit  of  no  partial  exceptions  or  favoritisms.  It 
would  be  binding  on  all.  It  would  be,  we  think,  desired  by  all  who  hope  to  be 
benefited  by  the  change.  A  master  who,  out  of  spite,  obstinacy,  or  the  spirit  of 
martyrdom,  would  kick  at  a  speech,  or  remain  obdurate  to  a  sermon,  would  bow 
before  the  majesty  of  the  law.  There  is  more  eloquence  in  a  tiny  penal  clause 
imposing  a  fine  of  £$  than  in  the  graceful  benevolence  of  Lord  John  Manners 
or  the  historical  resumes  of  Dr.  Vaughan.  No  man  would  resist  it  often,  or 
resist  it  long.  ...  Let  the  young  men  and  women  .  .  .  appeal  to  Parliament 
to  ratify  by  its  fiat  that  principle  which  should  be  the  boast  and  the  mission 
of  every  Legislature — to  protect  the  poor  from  contumely  and  the  weak  from 
oppression.' 


Economic  Characteristics  805 

the  whole  community  that  their  task  required  for  its  proper 
fulfilment  more  than  ordinary  leisure  and  income,  there  is 
no  reason  why  they  should  not  ask  to  have  these  exceptional 
conditions  embodied  in  a  new  Common  Rule  and  secured  by 
law.  But  the  attempts  of  the  different  trades  to  force  up 
their  wages  and  other  conditions  above  the  National  Mini- 
mum, must,  as  we  have  learnt,  be  purely  experimental.  In 
so  far  as  any  rise  in  the  level  of  the  Common  Rule  results 
in  an  increase  in  the  efficiency  of  the  industry,  each  Trade 
Union  can  safely  push  its  own  interests.  But  any  such 
attempt  will  be  dependent  for  success  on  forces  which  cannot 
be  foreseen,  and  many  of  which  are  unconnected  with  the 
efficiency  of  the  manual  workers  themselves.  The  rapidity 
of  industrial  invention  in  the  particular  trade,  the  extent  to 
which  it  is  recruited  by  additional  brain-workers,  the  ease 
with  which  new  capital  can  be  obtained,  will  determine  how 
far  and  how  quickly  the  Trade  Union  can,  by  raising  its 
Common  Rule,  stimulate  increased  efficiency  and  concentrate 
the  business  in  its  most  advantageous  centres.  And  there 
is  also  another  direction  in  which,  under  a  system  of  private 
enterprise,  a  Trade  Union  may  successfully  push  its  members' 
claims.  In  our  chapter  on  "  The  Higgling  of  the  Market  "  we 
have  seen  how  nearly  every  section  of  capitalists  throws  up 
its  own  bulwark  against  the  stream  of  pressure,  in  order  to 
enjoy  its  own  particular  pool  of  profit.  A  legal  monopoly 
or  exclusive  concession,  a  ring  or  syndicate,  will  secure  for 
the  capitalists  of  the  trade  exemption  from  competition  and 
exceptional  gains.  The  same  result  occurs  whenever  there 
is  a  sudden  rush  of  demand  for  a  new  product,  or  a  sudden 
cheapening  of  production.  If  the  wage -earners  in  these 
trades  are  strongly  organised,  they  can  extract  some  part  of 
these  exceptional  profits,  which  the  employers  will  concede 
if  they  are  threatened  with  a  complete  stoppage  of  the 
industry.  From  the  point  of  view  of  the  community  there 
is  no  reason  against  this  "sharing  of  the  plunder,"  as  the 
expenditure  of  the  workmen's  share,  distributed  over  thousands 
of  families,  is  quite  as  likely  to  be  socially  advantageous  as 


806  Trade  Union  Theory 

that  of  the  swollen  incomes  of  a  comparatively  small  number 
of  newly-enriched  employers.1 

For  these  and  all  other  kinds  of  "  Rent  of  Opportunity," 
the  law  is  obviously  quite  inapplicable.  In  short,  for  every- 
thing beyond  the  National  Minimum,  and  the  technical 
interpretation  of  this  to  secure  to  each  trade  the  conditions 
necessary  for  efficient  citizenship,  the  wage-earners  must  rely 
on  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining. 

1  But  here  again  we  must  remind  the  reader  that  the  Trade  Union  cannot, 
by  any  Common  Rule,  trench  upon  the  exceptional  profits  of  particular  firms. 
Patents  and  Trade  Marks,  advertising  specialities  and  proprietary  articles  are 
therefore  beyond  its  reach.  It  is  only  when,  as  in  the  case  of  the  Birmingham 
Alliances,  the  swollen  profits  extend  over  the  whole  industry  that  the  Trade 
Union  can  effectively  insist  on  sharing  the  plunder.  And  it  so  happens  that  in 
these  cases  the  wage-earners  are  seldom  sufficiently  well  organised  even  to  defend 
their  own  position.  When  the  enlarged  profits  of  the  trade  arise  from  a  sudden 
rush  of  demand  or  a  sudden  cheapening  of  production,  it  is  usually  a  question  (as 
in  the  case  of  the  sewing-machine  and  the  bicycle)  of  a  new  product  or  a  new 
process,  produced  by  workers  who,  newly  gathered  together,  are  unprotected 
by  effective  combination.  Accordingly,  though  the  wage-earners  in  exceptionally 
profitable  industries  often  obtain  continuous  employment,  and  a  slight  rise  of 
wages,  they  practically  never  secure  any  appreciable  share  of  the  "  pools  of  profit " 
that  we  have  described.  Thus  whilst  the  brewers,  wholesale  provision  merchants, 
patent  medicine  proprietors,  soap  and  pill  advertisers,  wholesale  clothiers, 
sewing-machine  makers,  bicycle  and  pneumatic  tyre  manufacturers,  and  the 
mineral  water  merchants  have  all  during  the  past  eight  years  been  making 
colossal  profits,  the  wage -earners  employed  in  these  trades,  who  are  almost 
entirely  unorganised,  stand,  on  the  whole,  rather  below  than  above  the  average 
of  the  kingdom.  In  many  of  these  cases  the  conditions  of  the  wage-earners 
have  remained  actually  below  the  level  of  "a  Living  Wage." 


CHAPTER    IV 

TRADE    UNIONISM    AND    DEMOCRACY 

IT  might  easily  be  contended  that  Trade  Unionism  has  no 
logical  or  necessary  connection  with  any  particular  kind  of 
state  or  form  of  administration.  If  we  consider  only  its 
fundamental  object — the  deliberate  regulation  of  the  condi- 
tions of  employment  in  such  a  way  as  to  ward  off  from 
the  manual-working  producers  the  evil  effects  of  industrial 
competition — there  is  clearly  no  incompatibility  between 
this  and  any  kind  of  government.  Regulations  of  this  type 
have  existed,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  under  emperors  and  presi- 
dents, aristocracies  and  democracies.  The  spread  of  the 
Industrial  Revolution  and  the  enormous  development  of 
international  trade  have  everywhere  brought  the  evils  of 
unregulated  competition  into  sensational  prominence.  The 
wise  autocrat  of  to-day,  conversant  with  the  latest  results  of 
economic  science,  and  interested  in  the  progressive  improve- 
ment of  his  state,  might,  therefore,  be  as  eager  to  prevent 
the  growth  of  industrial  parasitism  as  the  most  democratic 
politician.  Hence,  we  can  easily  imagine  such  an  autocrat 
enforcing  a  National  Minimum,  which  should  rule  out  of 
the  industrial  system  all  forms  of  competition  degrading  to 
the  health,  intelligence,  or  character  of  his  people.  The 
rapid  extension  of  factory  legislation  in  semi -autocratic 
countries  during  recent  years  indicates  that  some  inkling  of 
this  truth  is  reaching  the  minds  of  European  bureaucracies. 
What  is  distrusted  in  modern  Trade  Unionism  is  not  its 


808  Trade  Union  Theory 

object,  nor  even  its  devices,  but  its  structure  and  its  methods. 
When  workmen  meet  together  to  discuss  their  grievances — 
still  more,  when  they  form  associations  of  national  extent, 
raise  an  independent  revenue,  elect  permanent  representative 
committees,  and  proceed  to  bargain  and  agitate  as  corporate 
bodies — they  are  forming,  within  the  state,  a  spontaneous 
democracy  of  their  own.  The  autocrat  might  see  in  this 
industrial  democracy  nothing  more  hostile  to  his  supremacy 
in  the  state  than  the  self-government  of  the  village  or  the 
co-operative  store.  It  is,  we  imagine,  on  this  view  that  the 
Czar  of  All  the  Russias  regards  with  complacency  the  spon- 
taneous activity  of  the  Mir  and  the  Artel.  More  usually, 
however,  the  autocrat  distrusts  the  educational  influence  of 
even  the  most  subordinate  forms  of  self-government.  And 
when  the  association  is  national  in  extent,  composed  ex- 
clusively of  one  class,  and  untrammelled  by  any  compulsory 
constitution,  his  faith  in  its  objects  or  his  tolerance  for  its 
devices  becomes  completely  submerged  beneath  his  fear  of 
its  apparently  revolutionary  organisation.1  Hence,  though 
European  autocracies  may  greatly  extend  their  factory 
legislation,  and  might  even,  on  the  advice  of  the  economists 
or  in  response  to  the  public  opinion  of  the  wage-earning 
class,  deliberately  enforce  a  National  Minimum  of  education, 
sanitation,  leisure,  and  wages,  they  are  not  likely  to  encourage 
that  pushing  forward  of  the  Common  Rules  of  each  section 
by  the  method  of  Collective  Bargaining,  which  is  so  char- 
acteristic of  British  Trade  Unionism,  and  upon  which,  as  we 
have  seen,  the  maximum  productivity  of  the  community  as 
a  whole  depends.2 

The  problem  of  how  far  Trade  Unionism  is  consistent 
with  autocratic  government — important  to  the  continental 
student — is  not  of  practical  concern  to  the  Anglo-Saxon. 

1  In  this  respect,  the  old-fashioned  Liberal  stood  at  the  opposite  pole  from 
the  autocrat.     What  he  liked  in  Trade  Unionism  was  the  voluntary  spontaneity 
of  its  structure  and  the  self-helpfulness  of  its  methods  ;  even  when  he  disbelieved 
in  the  possibility  of  its  objects,  and  disliked  its  devices. 

2  It  would  seem  to  follow  that,  if  we  could  suppose  other  things  to  be  equal,  an 
autocracy  would  not  attain  so  great  a  national  wealth-production  as  a  democracy. 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  809 

In  the  English-speaking  world  institutions  which  desire  to 
maintain  and  improve  their  position  must  at  all  hazards 
bring  themselves  into  line  with  democracy.  The  wise 
official  who  has  to  function  under  the  control  of  a  committee 
of  management,  carefully  considers  its  modes  of  action  and 
the  interests  and  opinions  of  its  members,  so  that  he  may 
shape  and  state  his  policy  in  such  a  way  as  to  avoid  the 
rejection  of  the  measure  he  desires.  In  the  same  way  each 
section  of  Trade  Unionists  will  have  to  put  forward  a  policy 
of  which  no  part  runs  counter  to  the  interests  and  ideals  of 
the  bulk  of  the  people.  Believing,  as  we  do,  in  the  social 
expediency  both  of  popular  government,  and  of  a  wisely 
directed  Trade  Unionism  for  each  class  of  producers,  we 
shall  end  our  work  by  suggesting  with  what  modifications 
and  extensions,  and  subject  to  what  limitations,  British 
Trade  Unionism  can  best  fulfil  its  legitimate  function  in 
the  modern  democratic  state.  At  this  point,  therefore,  we 
leave  behind  the  exposition  and  analysis  of  facts,  and  their 
generalisation  into  economic  theory,  in  order  to  pass  over 
into  precept  and  prophecy. 

We  see  at  once  that  the  complete  acceptance  of  demo- 
cracy, with  its  acute  consciousness  of  the  interests  of  the 
community  as  a  whole,  and  its  insistence  on  equality  of 
opportunity  for  all  citizens,  will  necessitate  a  reconsidera- 
tion by  the  Trade  Unionists  of  their  three  Doctrines — the 
abandonment  of  one,  the  modification  of  another,  and  the 
far-reaching  extension  and  development  of  the  third.1  To 
begin  with  the  Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests,  we  may  infer 
that,  whatever  respect  may  be  paid  to  the  "  established 
expectations  "  of  any  class,  this  will  not  be  allowed  to  take 
the  form  of  a  resistance  to  inventions,  or  of  any  obstruction 
of  improvements  in  industrial  processes.  Equitable  con- 
sideration of  the  interests  of  existing  workers  will  no  doubt 
be  more  and  more  expected,  and  popular  governments  may 
even  adopt  Mill's  suggestion  of  making  some  provision  for 
operatives  displaced  by  a  new  machine.  But  this  con- 

1  See  Part  II.  chap.  xiii.  "The  Assumptions  of  Trade  Unionism." 


8io  Trade  Union  Theory 

sideration  and  this  provision  will  certainly  not  take  the  form 
of  restricting  the  entrance  to  a  trade,  or  of  recognising  any 
exclusive  right  to  a  particular  occupation  or  service.  Hence 
the  old  Trade  Union  conception  of  a  vested  interest  in  an 
occupation  must  be  entirely  given  up — a  change  of  front 
will  be  the  more  easy  in  that,  as  we  have  seen,1  no  union  is 
now  able  to  embody  this  conception  in  a  practical  policy. 

Coming  now  to  the  Doctrine  of  Supply  and  Demand, 
we  see  that  any  attempt  to  better  the  strategic  position  of  a 
particular  section  by  the  Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers 
will  be  unreservedly  condemned.  Not  only  is  this  Device 
inconsistent  with  the  democratic  instinct  in  favor  of  opening 
up  the  widest  possible  opportunity  for  every  citizen,  but  it 
is  hostile  to  the  welfare  of  the  community  as  a  whole,  and 
especially  to  the  manual  workers,  in  that  it  tends  to  dis- 
tribute the  capital,  brains,  and  labor  of  the  nation  less 
productively  than  would  otherwise  be  the  case.2  Trade 
Unionism  has,  therefore,  absolutely  to  abandon  one  of  its 
two  Devices.  This  throwing  off  of  the  old  Adam  of 
monopoly  will  be  facilitated  by  the  fact  that  the  mobility 
of  modern  industry  has,  in  all  but  a  few  occupations,  already 
made  any  effective  use  of  Restriction  of  Numbers  quite 
impracticable.3  Even  if,  in  particular  cases,  the  old  Device 
should  again  become  feasible,  those  Trade  Unions  which 
practised  it  would  be  placing  themselves  directly  in  antag- 
onism to  the  conscious  interests  of  the  remainder  of  their 
own  class,  and  of  the  community  as  a  whole.  And  in  so 
far  as  industry  passes  from  the  hands  of  private  capitalists 
into  the  control  of  representatives  of  the  consumers,  whether 
in  the  form  of  voluntary  co-operative  societies,4  or  in  that  of 

1  Part  II.  chaps,  x.  and  xi.  "  The  Entrance  to  a  Trade  "  and  "  The  Right  to 
a  Trade." 

2  See     Part    III.    chap.     iii.    "The    Economic    Characteristics    of    Trade 
Unionism,"  under  the  heading  "  The  Device  of  Restriction  of  Numbers." 

3  See  Part  II.  chap.  x.  "  The  Entrance  to  a  Trade." 

4  Here  and  elsewhere  in  this  chapter  we  mean  by  co-operative  societies  the 
characteristic  British  type  of  associations  of  consumers,  who  unite  for  the  purpose 
of  carrying  on,   by   salaried   service,    the    manufacture  and   distribution   of  the 
commodities  they  desire.     This  form  of  co-operative  society — the  "store  "and 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  8 1 1 

the  municipality  or  the  central  government,  any  interference 
with  freedom  to  choose  the  best  man  or  woman  for  every 
vacancy,  more  and  more  consciously  condemned  by  public 
opinion,  will  certainly  not  be  tolerated. 

But  the  manipulation  of  the  labor  market  to  the 
advantage  of  particular  sections  does  not  always  take  the 
form  of  a  limitation  of  apprenticeship,  or  any  Restriction  of 
Numbers.  Among  the  Cotton -spinners  the  piecers,  and 
among  the  Cotton-weavers  the  tenters,  are  engaged  and  paid 
by  the  operatives  themselves,  whose  earnings  are  accordingly 
partly  made  up  of  the  profit  on  this  juvenile  labor.  It 
therefore  suits  the  interest  of  the  adult  workers,  no  less  than 
that  of  the  capitalist  manufacturers,  that  there  should  be  as 
little  restriction  as  possible  on  the  age  or  numbers  of  these 
subordinate  learners:  the  Cotton -spinners,  in  fact,  as  we 
have  more  than  once  mentioned,  go  so  far  as  to  insist  on 
there  being  always  ten  times  as  many  of  them  as  would 
suffice  to  recruit  the  trade.  In  this  parasitic  use  of  child- 
labor,  the  Cotton  Operatives  are  sharing  with  the  manu- 
facturers what  is  virtually  a  subsidy  from  the  community  as 
a  whole.  The  enforcement  of  a  National  Minimum  would, 


the  "wholesale,"  together  with  their  adjunct,  the  Co-operative  Corn  Mill — 
accounts  for  nineteen-twentieths  of  the  capital,  practically  all  the  distributive 
trade,  and  three-fourths  of  the  aggregate  production  of  the  British  Co-operative 
Movement  (Third  Annual  Report  of  the  Labour  Department  of  the  Board  of 
Trade,  C.  8230,  1896,  pp.  25-48).  Though  the  commodities  and  services 
supplied  by  voluntary  associations  of  consumers  will  vary  from  time  to  time,  we 
regard  this  type  of  co-operative  society  as  a  permanent  element  in  the  democratic 
state.  However  widely  we  may  extend  the  scope  of  central  or  local  government, 
there  will  always  be  a  place  for  voluntary  associations  of  consumers  to  provide 
for  themselves  what  the  public  authority  either  cannot  or  will  not  supply.  The 
other  type  of  organisation  known  as  a  co-operative  society,  the  association  of 
producers,  or  so-called  "productive  society,"  stands  in  a  very  different  position. 
We  see  no  future  for  this  in  the  fully-developed  democratic  state.  In  its  original 
ideal  form  of  a  self-governing  association  of  manual  workers,  it  seems  to  us 
(besides  being  open  to  grave  objections)  to  have  been  made  impossible  by  the 
Great  Industry,  whilst  the  subsequent  forms  known  as  "co-partnership"  appear 
to  us  to  be  incompatible  with  Trade  Unionism,  and  the  indispensable  mainten- 
ance of  the  Common  Rule.  See  The  Co-operative  Movement  in  Great  Britain 
(2nd  edition,  London,  1894),  and  7^he  Relationship  between  Co-operation  and  Trade 
Unionism  (Co-operative  Union  pamphlet,  Manchester,  1892),  both  by  Mrs. 
Sidney  Webb. 


812  Trade  Union  Theory 

as  we  have  seen,1  involve  such  a  raising  of  the  minimum 
age,  both  for  half  and  whole  time  employment,  as  would 
put  a  stop  to  this  particular  expression  of  corporate  self-help. 
Thus,  the  Doctrine  of  Supply  and  Demand  will  have  to 
manifest  itself  exclusively  in  the  persistent  attempts  of  each 
trade  to  specialise  its  particular  grade  of  skill,  by  progres- 
sively raising  the  level  of  its  own  Common  Rules.  In  so  far 
as  this  results  in  a  corresponding  increase  in  efficiency  it 
will,  as  we  have  shown,2  not  only  benefit  the  trade  itself,  but 
also  cause  the  capital,  brains,  and  labor  of  the  community 
to  be  distributed  in  the  most  productive  way.  And  the 
demands  of  each  grade  will,  in  the  absence  of  any  Restric- 
tion of  Numbers  or  resistance  to  innovations,  be  automat- 
ically checked  by  the  liberty  of  the  customer  to  resort 
to  an  alternative  product  and  the  absolute  freedom  of  the 
directors  of  industry  to  adopt  an  alternative  process,  or  to 
select  another  grade  of  labor.  Thus,  the  permanent  bias  of 
the  manual  worker  towards  higher  wages  and  shorter  hours 
of  labor  is  perpetually  being  counteracted  by  another — his 
equally  strong  desire  for  continuity  of  employment.  If  the 
Common  Rule  in  any  industry  at  any  time  is  pressed  upward 
further  or  more  quickly  than  is  compensated  for  by  an 
equivalent  advance  in  the  efficiency  of  the  industry,  the  cost 
of  production,  and,  therefore,  the  price,  will  be  raised,  and  the 
consumers'  demand  for  that  particular  commodity  will,  in 
the  vast  majority  of  cases,  be  thereby  restricted.  The  rise 
of  wages  will,  in  such  a  case,  have  been  purchased  at  the 
cost  of  throwing  some  men  out  of  work.  And  though  the 
working-class  official  cannot,  any  more  than  the  capitalist 
or  the  economist,  predict  the  effect  on  demand  of  any 
particular  rise  of  wages,  even  the  most  aggressive  members 
of  a  Trade  Union  discover,  in  an  increase  of  the  percentage 
of  unemployed  colleagues  whom  they  have  to  maintain, 
an  unmistakable  and  imperative  check  upon  any  repeti- 

1  Part  III.  chap.  ill.  "The  Economic  Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism." 

2  Ibid,  under  the  heading  "The  Effect  of  the  Sectional  Application  of  the 
Common  Rule  on  the  Distribution  of  Industry." 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  8 1 3 

tion  of  an  excessive  claim.  How  constantly  and  effec- 
tively this  check  operates  on  the  mind  of  the  Trade 
Union  officials  can  be  realised  only  by  those  who  have 
heard  their  private  discussions,  or  who  have  watched  the 
silent  postponement  of  cherished  aims  by  particular  unions. 
It  is  not  fear  of  the  employers'  strength,  or  lack  of  desire 
for  shorter  hours  that  is  (1897)  preventing  the  Cotton 
Operatives  from  using  their  power  to  obtain  an  eight 
hours'  day  or  a  rise  in  their  piecework  rates,  but  the  ever- 
present  dread,  quickened  by  the  sight  of  unemployed 
spinners  and  weavers  on  short-time,  of  driving  away  some  of 
the  trade  of  Lancashire.  Paradoxical  as  it  may  seem,  the 
sins  of  the  Trade  Unions  in  this  respect  would  tend  to  be 
those  of  omission  rather  than  those  of  commission.  Whether 
with  regard  to  sanitation,  hours,  or  wages,  each  Trade  Union 
would,  in  its  fear  of  encouraging  new  inventions,  be  apt  to 
stop  short  in  its  claims  at  an  earlier  point  than  the  fullest 
efficiency  demanded,  rather  than  push  ever  onward  the 
specialisation  of  its  craft,  at  the  cost  of  seeing  some  part 
of  it,  to  the  common  advantage,  superseded  by  another 
process.1 

So  far  democracy  may  be  expected  to  look  on  com- 
placently at  the  fixing,  by  mutual  agreement  between  the 
directors  of  industry  and  the  manual  workers,  of  special 
rates  of  wages  for  special  classes.  But  this  use  of  the 
Method  of  Collective  Bargaining  for  the  advantage  of  parti- 
cular sections — this  "  freedom  of  contract "  between  capitalists 
and  wage-earners — will  become  increasingly  subject  to  the 
fundamental  condition  that  the  business  of  the  community 
must  not  be  interfered  with.  When  in  the  course  of  bar- 
gaining there  ensues  a  deadlock  2 — when  the  workmen  strike, 
or  the  employers  lock  out — many  other  interests  are  affected 
than  those  of  the  parties  concerned.  We  may  accordingly 
expect  that,  whenever  an  industrial  dispute  reaches  a  certain 

1  See  Part  II.  chap.  viii.  "  New  Processes  and  Machinery." 

2  See  Part  IT.  chap.  ii.  "The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining,"  chap.  iii. 
"Arbitration,"  and  chap.  iv.  "The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment." 


8 14  Trade  Union  Theory 

magnitude,  a  democratic  state  will,  in  the  interests  of  the 
community  as  a  whole,  not  scruple  to  intervene,  and  settle 
the  points  at  issue  by  an  authoritative  fiat.  The  growing 
impatience  with  industrial  dislocation  will,  in  fact,  where 
Collective  Bargaining  breaks  down,  lead  to  its  supersession 
by  some  form  of  compulsory  arbitration  ;  that  is  to  say,  by 
Legal  Enactment.1  And  when  the  fixing  of  the  conditions 
on  which  any  industry  is  to  be  carried  on,  is  thus  taken  out 
of  the  hands  of  employers  and  workmen,  the  settlement  will 
no  longer  depend  exclusively  on  the  strategic  position  of  the 
parties,  or  of  the  industry,  but  will  be  largely  influenced  by 

1  In  this  connection,  the  provisions  of  the  New  Zealand  Industrial  Concilia- 
tion and  Arbitration  Act,  drafted  and  carried  through  by  the  Hon.  W.  P. 
Reeves,  are  highly  significant.  By  this  Act  (No.  14  of  1894,  slightly  amended 
by  No.  30  of  1865  and  No.  57  of  1896)  there  is  created  a  complete  system  of 
industrial  tribunals  for  dealing,  from  the  standpoint  of  the  public  interest,  not 
only  with  the  interpretation  and  enforcement  of  collective  agreements  expressly 
made  subject  to  them ;  but  also  with  industrial  disputes  of  every  kind.  There 
is,  first,  in  each  district  a  Board  of  Conciliation,  consisting  in  equal  numbers  of 
members  elected  by  the  employers'  and  workmen's  associations  respectively, 
with  an  impartial  chairman  chosen  by  the  Board  from  outside  itself.  Any  party 
to  an  industrial  dispute — that  is  to  say,  an  association  of  employers  or  of  work- 
men, or  one  or  more  employers  though  not  associated — may  bring  the  quarrel 
before  the  Board,  which  is  thereon  required,  whether  the  other  party  consents  or 
not,  to  inquire  into  the  dispute,  and  do  its  best  to  promote  a  settlement.  If 
conciliation  fails  the  Board  is  then  required,  within  two  months  of  the  first 
application  to  it,  to  "decide  the  question  according  to  the  merits  and  substantial 
justice  of  the  case."  So  far,  the  system  is  merely  one  of  Compulsory  Arbitration, 
with  a  formal  award  which  the  parties  are  not  bound  to  accept.  But  the  Board 
may,  if  it  thinks  fit,  refer  any  unsettled  dispute,  with  or  without  its  own  decision 
on  its  merits,  to  the  central  Court  of  Arbitration,  consisting  of  three  members 
appointed  by  the  Governor,  two  on  the  nomination  respectively  of  the  associa- 
tions of  employers  and  employed,  and  one,  who  presides,  from  among  the  Judges 
of  the  Supreme  Court.  If  the  local  Board  does  not  so  remit  the  case,  any  party 
to  it  may  require  the  Board's  report  to  be  referred  to  the  Court.  The  Court  is 
thereupon  required  to  investigate  the  dispute  in  the  most  complete  manner,  with 
or  without  the  assent  of  any  of  the  parties,  and  with  all  the  powers  of  a  court  of 
justice.  Its  award  is,  in  all  cases,  nominally  binding  on  the  associations  or 
persons  specified  therein,  for  the  period  (not  exceeding  two  years)  named  ;  and 
any  award  which  refers  to  an  association  is  binding  not  only  upon  all  those 
who  are  members  at  the  date  of  the  award,  but  also  upon  all  those  who  sub- 
sequently join  during  its  continuance.  But  though  the  award  is  nominally 
binding,  it  is  within  the  discretion  of  the  Court  whether  it  shall  be  legally 
enforcible.  The  Court  may,  if  it  thinks  fit,  either  at  once,  or,  on  the  applica- 
tion of  any  of  the  parties,  subsequently,  file  its  award  in  the  Supreme  Court 
office,  when  it  becomes,  by  leave  of  the  Court,  enforcible  as  if  it  were  a  judg- 
ment of  the  Supreme  Court.  The  award  may  include  an  order  to  pay  costs  and 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  8 1 5 

the  doctrine  of  a  living  wage.  The  Trade  Union  official 
would  then  have  to  prove  that  the  claims  of  his  clients  were 
warranted  by  the  greater  intensity  of  their  effort,  or  by  the 
rareness  of  their  skill  in  comparison  with  those  of  the  lowest 
grade  of  labor  receiving  only  the  National  Minimum  ;  whilst 
the  case  of  the  associated  employers  would  have  to  rest  on 
a  demonstration,  both  that  the  conditions  demanded  were 
unnecessary,  if  not  prejudicial,  to  the  workmen's  efficiency, 
and  that  equally  competent  recruits  could  be  obtained  in 
sufficient  numbers  without  the  particular  "  rent  of  ability," 
demanded  by  the  Trade  Union  over  and  above  the  National 
Minimum. 

expenses,  and  penalties  for  its  breach,  not  exceeding  ;£io  against  an  individual 
workman  or  ^500  against  an  association  or  an  individual  employer.  The  decision 
of  the  Court  of  Arbitration,  acting  by  a  majority  of  its  members,  may,  therefore, 
at  its  discretion,  be  made  part  of  the  law  of  the  land.  When  a  dispute  has  once 
been  brought  before  a  Board  or  the  Court,  "  any  act  or  thing  in  the  nature  of  a 
strike  or  lock-out "  is  expressly  prohibited,  and  would  presumably  be  punishable 
as  contempt. 

During  the  three  years  that  this  Act  has  been  in  force,  there  have  been  alto- 
gether sixteen  labor  disputes,  and  it  has  been  successfully  applied  to  every  one  of 
them,  half  being  settled  by  the  Boards  of  Conciliation  and  half  by  the  Court  of 
Arbitration.  The  awards  have  been  uniformly  well  received  by  the  parties,  and 
appear  to  have  been  generally  obeyed.  Several  of  them  were  filed  in  the 
Supreme  Court,  and  have  thus  obtained  the  force  of  law.  So  far  the  Act  has 
been  entirely  successful  in  preventing  the  dislocation  of  industry.  This  success 
is  no  doubt  largely  due  to  the  general  support  given  by  public  opinion  in  the 
Colony  to  the  principle  of  arbitration.  There  is  at  present  no  provision  enab- 
ling the  Boards  or  the  Court  to  deal  with  a  dispute,  however  disastrous  to  the 
public  welfare,  in  which  none  of  the  parties  request  its  intervention.  And  as 
there  has  been  as  yet  no  refusal  to  obey  any  of  the  awards,  the  actual  process  of 
enforcement  has  not  been  tested  in  the  law  courts.  It  has  been  suggested  that 
an  obstinate  employer,  refusing  to  join  any  association,  and  employing  only  non- 
unionists,  might  escape  jurisdiction  by  declining  to  recognise  (and  therefore 
having  no  quarrel  with)  any  Trade  Union.  Such  a  case  occurred  in  South 
Australia,  where  a  less  ably  drafted  Act  on  somewhat  the  same  lines  as  that  of 
New  Zealand  is  in  force.  The  point  was,  however,  not  judicially  decided 
("Quelques  Experiences  de  Conciliation  par  1'Etat  en  Australie,"  by  Anton 
Bertram  in  Revue  (TEconomie  Politique,  1897).  In  the  present  state  of  public 
opinion  in  New  Zealand,  this  or  any  other  evasion  of  the  law  would  be  very 
narrowly  viewed  by  the  judges,  and  any  flaw  discovered  would  be  promptly 
cured  by  an  amending  Act.  The  Board  or  Court  might  easily  be  empowered  to 
deal,  on  its  own  initiative,  with  any  dispute  that  it  considered  injurious  to  the 
community,  and  also  to  take  cognisance,  as  a  dispute,  of  any  wholesale  dis- 
missal of  workmen,  or  of  any  explicit  refusal  to  employ  members  of  a  duly 
registered  association. 


816  Trade  Union  Theory 

It  is  accordingly  on  the  side  of  the  Doctrine  of  a  Living 
Wage  that  the  present  policy  of  Trade  Unionism  will  require 
most  extension.  Democratic  public  opinion  will  expect  each 
trade  to  use  its  strategic  position  to  secure  the  conditions 
necessary  for  the  fulfilment  of  its  particular  social  function 
in  the  best  possible  way — to  obtain,  that  is  to  say,  not  what 
will  be  immediately  most  enjoyed  by  the  "  average  sensual 
man,"  but  what,  in  the  long  run,  will  most  conduce  to  his 
efficiency  as  a  professional,  a  parent,  and  a  citizen.  This 
will  involve  some  modification  of  Trade  Union  policy. 
Powerful  Trade  Unions  show  no  backwardness  in  exacting 
the  highest  money  wages  that  they  know  how  to  obtain  ;  but 
even  the  best  organised  trades  will  at  present  consent,  as  a 
part  of  their  bargain  with  the  employer,  to  work  for  excessive 
and  irregular  hours,  and  to  put  up  with  unsafe,  insanitary, 
indecent,  and  hideous  surroundings.1  In  all  the  better-paid 
crafts  in  the  England  of  to-day,  shorter  and  more  regular 
hours,  greater  healthfulness,  comfort,  and  refinement  in  the 
conditions  of  work,  and  the  definite  provision  of  periodical 
holidays  for  recreation  and  travel,  are,  in  the  interests  of 
industrial  and  civic  efficiency,  more  urgently  required  than 
a  rise  in  the  Standard  Rate.  Such  an  application  of  the 
Doctrine  of  a  Living  Wage  will  involve,  not  only  a  growth 
of  deliberate  foresight  and  self-control  among  the  rank  and 
file,  but  also  a  development  of  capacity  in  the  Civil  Service 
of  the  Trade  Union  movement.  To  haggle  over  an  advance 
in  wages  is  within  the  capacity  of  any  labor  leader ;  to 
suggest  to  the  employer  and  the  legislature  the  "special 
rules"  calculated  to  ensure  the  maximum  comfort  to  the 
operatives,  and  cause  the  minimum  cost  and  inconvenience  to 
the  industry,  demands  a  higher  degree  of  technical  expertness.2 
Nor  is  it  enough  for  each  trade  to  maintain  and  raise  its 
own  Standard  of  Life.  Unless  the  better-paid  occupations 
are  to  be  insidiously  handicapped  in  the  competition  for  the 

1  See  Part  II.  chap.  vi.    "  The  Normal  Day,"  and  chap.  vii.   "  Sanitation 
and  Safety." 

2  See  Part  II.  chap,  vii,  "  Sanitation  and  Safety." 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  8 1 7 

home  and  foreign  market,  it  is,  as  we  have  demonstrated,1 
essential  that  no  one  of  the  national  industries  should  be 
permitted  to  become  parasitic  by  the  use  of  subsidised  or 
deteriorating  labor.  Hence  the  organised  trades  are  vitally 
concerned  in  the  abolition  of  "  sweating "  in  all  occupations 
whatsoever,  whether  these  compete  with  them  for  custom  by 
manufacturing  for  the  same  demand,  or  for  the  means  of 
production  by  diverting  the  organising  capacity  and  capital 
of  the  nation.  And  this  self-interest  of  the  better -paid 
trades  coincides,  as  we  have  seen,  with  the  welfare  of  the 
community,  dependent  as  this  is  on  securing  the  utmost 
development  of  health,  intelligence,  and  character  in  the 
weaker  as  well  as  in  the  stronger  sections.  Thus  we  arrive 
at  the  characteristic  device  of  the  Doctrine  of  a  Living  Wage, 
which  we  have  termed  the  National  Minimum — the  deliberate 
enforcement,  by  an  elaborate  Labor  Code,  of  a  definite  quota 
of  education,  sanitation,  leisure,  and  wages  for  every  grade 
of  workers  in  every  industry.2  This  National  Minimum  the 
public  opinion  of  the  democratic  state  will  not  only  support, 
but  positively  insist  on  for  the  common  weal.  But  public 
opinion  alone  will  not  suffice.  To  get  the  principle  of 
a  National  Minimum  unreservedly  adopted  ;  to  embody  it 
in  successive  Acts  of  Parliament  of  the  requisite  technical 
detail ;  to  see  that  this  legislation  is  properly  enforced  ;  to 
cause  the  regulations  to  be  promptly  and  intelligently  adapted 
to  changes  in  the  national  industry,  requires  persistent  effort 
and  specialised  skill.  For  this  task  no  section  of  the  com- 
munity is  so  directly  interested  and  so  well-equipped  as  the 
organised  trades,  with  their  prolonged  experience  of  industrial 
regulation  and  their  trained  official  staff.  It  is  accordingly 
upon  the  Trade  Unions  that  the  democratic  state  must 
mainly  rely  for  the  stimulus,  expert  counsel,  and  persistent 
watchfulness,  without  which  a  National  Minimum  can  neither 
be  obtained  nor  enforced. 

1  Part  III.  chap.  iii.  "The  Economic  Characteristics   of  Trade  Unionism" 
under  the  heading  "  Parasitic  Trades." 

2  Ibid,  under  the  heading  "The  National  Minimum." 

VOL.  II  ^  G 


818  Trade  Union  Theory 

This  survey  of  the  changes  required  in  Trade  Union 
policy  leads  us  straight  to  a  conclusion  as  to  the  part  which 
Trade  Unionism  will  be  expected  to  play  in  the  manage- 
ment of  the  industry  of  a  democratic  state.  The  intermin- 
able series  of  decisions,  which  together  make  up  industrial 
administration,  fall  into  three  main  classes.  There  is,  first, 
the  decision  as  to  what  shall  be  produced — that  is  to  say, 
the  exact  commodity  or  service  to  be  supplied  to  the  con- 
sumers. There  is,  secondly,  the  judgment  as  to  the  manner 
in  which  the  production  shall  take  place,  the  adoption  of 
material,  the  choice  of  processes,  and  the  selection  of  human 
agents.  Finally,  there  is  the  altogether  different  question  of 
the  conditions  under  which  these  human  agents  shall  be 
employed  —  the  temperature,  atmosphere,  and  sanitary 
arrangements  amid  which  they  shall  work,  the  intensity 
and  duration  of  their  toil,  and  the  wages  given  as  its 
reward. 

To  obtain  for  the  community  the  maximum  satisfaction 
it  is  essential  that  the  needs  and  desires  of  the  consumers 
should  be  the  main  factor  in  determining  the  commodities 
and  services  to  be  produced.  Whether  these  needs  and 
desires  can  best  be  ascertained  and  satisfied  by  the  private 
enterprise  of  capitalist  profit-makers,  keenly  interested  in 
securing  custom,  or  by  the  public  service  of  salaried  officials, 
intent  on  pleasing  associations  of  consumers  (as  in  the 
British  Co-operative  Movement)  or  associations  of  citizens 
(the  Municipality  or  the  State),  is  at  present  the  crucial 
problem  of  democracy.  But  whichever  way  this  issue 
may  be  decided,  one  thing  is  certain,  namely,  that 
the  several  sections  of  manual  workers,  enrolled  in  their 
Trade  Unions,  will  have,  under  private  enterprise  or 
Collectivism,  no  more  to  do  with  the  determination  of  what  is 
to  be  produced  than  any  other  citizens  or  consumers.  As 
manual  workers  and  wage-earners,  they  bring  to  the  problem 
no  specialised  knowledge,  and  as  persons  fitted  for  the  per- 
formance of  particular  services,  they  are  even  biassed  against 
the  inevitable  changes  in  demand  which  characterise  a 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  819 

progressive  community.1  This  is  even  more  the  case  with 
regard  to  the  second  department  of  industrial  administration 
— the  adoption  of  material,  the  choice  of  processes,  and  the 
selection  of  human  agents.  Here,  the  Trade  Unions  con- 
cerned are  specially  disqualified,  not  only  by  their  ignorance 
of  the  possible  alternatives,  but  also  by  their  overwhelming 
bias  in  favor  of  a  particular  material,  a  particular  process,  or 
a  particular  grade  of  workers,  irrespective  of  whether  these 
are  or  are  not  the  best  adapted  for  the  gratification  of  the 
consumers'  desires.  On  the  other  hand,  the  directors  of 
industry,  whether  thrown  up  by  the  competitive  struggle 
or  deliberately  appointed  by  the  consumers  or  citizens, 
have  been  specially  picked  out  and  trained  to  discover 
the  best  means  of  satisfying  the  consumers'  desires.  More- 
over, the  bias  of  their  self-interest  coincides  with  the  object 
of  their  customers  or  employers — that  is  to  say,  the  best 
and  cheapest  production.  Thus,  if  we  leave  out  of  account 
the  disturbing  influence  of  monopoly  in  private  enterprise, 
and  corruption  in  public  administration,  it  would  at  first  sight 
seem  as  if  we  might  safely  leave  the  organisation  of  pro- 
duction and  distribution  under  the  one  system  as  under  the 
other  to  the  expert  knowledge  of  the  directors  of  industry. 
But  this  is  subject  to  one  all-important  qualification.  The 
permanent  bias  of  the  profit-maker,  and  even  of  the  salaried 
official  of  the  Co-operative  Society,  the  Municipality,  or  the 
Government  Department,  is  to  lower  the  expense  of  pro- 
duction. So  far  as  immediate  results  are  concerned,  it  seems 
equally  advantageous  whether  this  reduction  of  cost  is  secured 
by  a  better  choice  of  materials,  processes,  or  men,  or  by  some 
lowering  of  wages  or  other  worsening  of  the  conditions  upon 
which  the  human  agents  are  employed.  But  the  democratic 
state  is,  as  we  have  seen,2  vitally  interested  in  upholding  the 
highest  possible  Standard  of  Life  of  all  its  citizens,  and 
especially  of  the  manual  workers  who  form  four-fifths  of  the 
whole.  Hence  the  bias  of  the  directors  of  industry  in  favor 

1  See  Part  II.  chap  ix.  "  Continuity  of  Employment." 
2  See  Part  III.  chap.  iii.  "  The  Economic  Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism," 


820  Trade  Union  Theory 

of  cheapness  has,  in  the  interests  of  the  community,  to  be 
perpetually  controlled  and  guided  by  a  determination  to 
maintain,  and  progressively  to  raise,  the  conditions  of 
employment. 

This  leads  us  to  the  third  branch  of  industrial  administra- 
tion— the  settlement  of  the  conditions  under  which  the  human 
beings  are  to  be  employed.  The  adoption  of  one  material 
rather  than  another,  the  choice  between  alternative  processes 
or  alternative  ways  of  organising  the  factory,  the  selection  of 
particular  grades  of  workers,  or  even  of  a  particular  foreman, 
may  affect,  for  the  worse,  the  Standard  of  Life  of  the  opera- 
tives concerned.  This  indirect  influence  on  the  conditions 
of  employment  passes  imperceptibly  into  the  direct  determi- 
nation of  the  wages,  hours,  *and  other  terms  of  the  wage 
contract.  On  all  these  matters  the  consumers,  on  the  one 
hand,  and  the  directors  of  industry  on  the  other,  are  per- 
manently disqualified  from  acting  as  arbiters.  In  our  chapter 
on  "  The  Higgling  of  the  Market " l  we  described  how  in  the 
elaborate  division  of  labor  which  characterises  the  modern 
industrial  system,  thousands  of  workers  co-operate  in  the 
bringing  to  market  of  a  single  commodity;  and  no  consumer, 
even  if  he  desired  it,  could  possibly  ascertain  or  judge  of  the 
conditions  of  employment  in  all  these  varied  trades.  Thus, 
the  consumers  of  all  classes  are  not  only  biassed  in  favor  of 
low  prices  :  they  are  compelled  to  accept  this  apparent  or 
genuine  cheapness  as  the  only  practicable  test  of  efficiency  of 
production.  And  though  the  immediate  employer  of  each 
section  of  workpeople  knows  the  hours  that  they  work  and 
the  wages  that  they  receive,  he  is  precluded  by  the  stream  of 
competitive  pressure,  transmitted  through  the  retail  shop- 
keeper and  the  wholesale  trader,  from  effectively  resisting  the 
promptings  of  his  own  self-interest  towards  a  constant 
cheapening  of  labor.  Moreover,  though  he  may  be  statistic- 
ally aware  of  the  conditions  of  employment,  his  lack  of 
personal  experience  of  those  conditions  deprives  him  of  any 
real  knowledge  of  their  effects.  To  the  brain-working  captain 

1   Part  III.  chap.  ii. 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  821 

of  industry,  maintaining  himself  and  his  family  on  thousands 
a  year,  the  manual-working  wage-earner  seems  to  belong  to 
another  species,  having  mental  faculties  and  bodily  needs 
altogether  different  from  his  own.  Men  and  women  of  the 
upper  or  middle  classes  are  totally  unable  to  realise  what 
state  of  body  and  mind,  what  level  of  character  and  conduct 
result  from  a  life  spent,  from  childhood  to  old  age,  amid 
the  dirt,  the  smell,  the  noise,  the  ugliness,  and  the  vitiated 
atmosphere  of  the  workshop  ;  under  constant  subjection  to 
the  peremptory,  or,  it  may  be,  brutal  orders  of  the  foreman  ; 
kept  continuously  at  laborious  manual  toil  for  sixty  or  seventy 
hours  in  every  week  of  the  year  ;  and  maintained  by  the  food, 
clothing,house-accommodation, recreation, and  family  lifewhich 
are  implied  by  a  precarious  income  of  between  ten  shillings  and 
two  pounds  a  week.  If  the  democratic  state  is  to  attain  its 
fullest  and  finest  development,  it  is  essential  that  the  actual 
needs  and  desires  of  the  human  agents  concerned  should  be 
the  main  considerations  in  determining  the  conditions  of 
employment.1  Here,  then,  we  find  the  special  function  of  the 
Trade  Union  in  the  administration  of  industry.  The  simplest 
member  of  the  working-class  organisation  knows  at  any  rate 
where  the  shoe  pinches.  The  Trade  Union  official  is  specially 
selected  by  his  fellow-workmen  for  his  capacity  to  express  the 
grievances  from  which  they  suffer,  and  is  trained  by  his  calling 
in  devising  remedies  for  them.  But  in  expressing  the  desires 
of  their  members,  and  in  insisting  on  the  necessary  reforms, 
the  Trade  Unions  act  within  the  constant  friction -brake 
supplied  by  the  need  of  securing  employment.  It  is  always 
the  consumers,  and  the  consumers  alone,  whether  they  act 
through  profit -making  entrepreneurs  or  through  their  own 
salaried  officials,  who  determine  how  many  of  each  particular 
grade  of  workers  they  care  to  employ  on  the  conditions 
demanded.2 

Thus,  it    is    for    the   consumers,  acting   either    through 

1  See  Part  II.  chap.  v.  "The  Standard  Rate,"  and  chap.  iii.  "Arbitration." 

2  This  was  the  conclusion  also  of  Fleeming  Jenkin's  mathematical  analysis  of 
abstract  economics.      "It  is  the  seller  of  labor  who  determines  the  price,  but  it  is 


822  Trade  Union  Theory 

capitalist  entrepreneurs  or  their  own  salaried  agents,  to  decide 
what  shall  be  produced.  It  is  for  the  directors  of -industry, 
whether  profit-makers  or  officials,  to  decide  how  it  shall  be 
produced,  though  in  this  decision  they  must  take  into  account 
the  objections  of  the  workers'  representatives  as  to  the  effect 
on  the  conditions  of  employment.  And,  in  the  settlement  of 
these  conditions,  it  is  for  the  expert  negotiators  of  the  Trade 
Unions,  controlled  by  the  desires  of  their  members,  to  state 
the  terms  under  which  each  grade  will  sell  its  labor.  But 
above  all  these,  stands  the  community  itself.  To  its  elected 
representatives  and  trained  Civil  Service  is  entrusted  the  duty 
of  perpetually  considering  the  permanent  interests  of  the  State 
as  a  whole.  When  any  group  of  consumers  desires  something 
which  is  regarded  as  inimical  to  the  public  wellbeing — for 
instance,  poisons,  explosives,  indecent  literature,  or  facilities 
for  sexual  immorality  or  gambling — the  community  prohibits 
or  regulates  the  satisfaction  of  these  desires.  When  the 
directors  of  industry  attempt  to  use  a  material,  or  a  process, 
which  is  regarded  as  injurious — for  instance,  food  products 
so  adulterated  as  to  be  detrimental  to  health,  ingredients 
poisonous  to  the  users,  or  processes  polluting  the  rivers  or  the 
atmosphere — their  action  is  restrained  by  Public  Health  Acts. 
And  when  the  workers  concerned,  whether  through  ignorance, 
indifference,  or  strategic  weakness,  consent  to  work  under 
conditions  which  impair  their  physique,  injure  their  intellect, 
or  degrade  their  character,  the  community  has,  for  its  own 
sake,  to  enforce  a  National  Minimum  of  education,  sanitation, 
leisure,  and  wages.  We  see,  therefore,  that  industrial  admini- 
stration is,  in  the  democratic  state,  a  more  complicated  matter 
than  is  na'fvely  imagined  by  the  old-fashioned  capitalist, 
demanding  the  "  right  to  manage  his  own  business  in  his  own 
way."  In  each  of  its  three  divisions,  the  interests  and  will  of 
one  or  other  section  is  the  dominant  factor.  But  no  section 

the  buyer  who  determines  the  number  of  transactions.  Capital  settles  how  many 
men  are  wanted  at  given  wages,  but  labor  settles  what  wages  the  man  shall 
have." — "  Graphic  Representation  of  the  Laws  of  Supply  and  Demand,"  by 
Fleeming  Jenkin,  in  Recess  Studies  (Edinburgh,  1870),  p.  184. 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  823 

wields  uncontrolled  sway  even  in  its  own  sphere.  The  State 
is  a  partner  in  every  enterprise.  In  the  interests  of  the 
community  as  a  whole,  no  one  of  the  interminable  series  of 
decisions  can  be  allowed  to  run  counter  to  the  consensus  of 
expert  opinion  representing  the  consumers  on  the  one  hand, 
the  producers  on  the  other,  and  the  nation  that  is  paramount 
over  both.1 

It  follows  from  this  analysis  that  Trade  Unionism  is  not 
merely  an  incident  of  the  present  phase  of  capitalist  industry, 
but  has  a  permanent  function  to  fulfil  in  the  democratic  state. 

1  Some  of  the  ablest  Trade  Union  officials  have  already  arrived  at  practically 
this  analysis.  Thus,  the  last  annual  report  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of 
Engineers,  written  by  Mr.  George  Barnes,  the  new  General  Secretary,  contains 
an  interesting  exposition  of  the  modern  Trade  Union  view  as  to  the  respective 
functions  of  the  employers  and  the  workmen  in  industrial  administration.  The 
interest  of  the  wage-earners  and  that  of  the  community  are,  it  is  argued,  identical, 
"  inasmuch  as  it  is  of  public  importance  that  a  high  standard  of  wages,  and  there- 
fore a  high  purchasing  power,  should  be  maintained.  The  employer,  on  the 
other  hand,  claims  absolute  freedom  to  exercise  authority  in  the  selection  and 
placing  and  paying  of  workmen,  because  he  says  he  provides  the  machinery  and 
plant.  But  he  forgets  that  this  freedom  in  the  conduct  generally  of  business  has 
long  since  been  taken  away  from  him,  and  that  he  now  only  has  liberty  to  conduct 
industrial  enterprise  in  accordance  with  public  opinion,  as  embodied  in  Parlia- 
mentary enactment  and  the  pressure  of  Trade  Unionism.  As  a  result  of  these 
humanising  influences,  hours  of  labor  have  been  reduced,  boy-labor  curtailed, 
machinery  fenced,  and  workshops  cleansed.  In  short,  competition  has  been  forced 
up  to  a  higher  plane  with  immense  advantage  to  the  commonweal,  so  that  the 
employer's  plea  '  to  do  what  he  likes  with  his  own '  is  somewhat  out  of  date,  and 
cannot  be  sustained.  We  are  willing,  however,  to  admit  that  in  certain  directions 
both  employer  and  employed  should  have  freedom  of  action.  Our  society,  for 
instance,  has  never  questioned  the  right  of  the  employer  to  terminate  contracts, 
to  select  and  discriminate  between  workmen,  and  to  pay  according  to  merit  or 
skill.  But  it  has  stipulated,  and  has  a  right  to  stipulate,  for  the  observance  of  a 
standard  or  minimum  wage  as  a  basis.  And  if,  as  has  been  stated  by  the 
Employers'  Council,  the  introduction  of  machinery  has  simplified  production,  and 
widened  the  difference  as  between  the  skill  of  the  machine  and  the  hand  operative, 
then  the  wage  of  the  handicraftsmen  should  be  proportionately  increased.  The 
introduction  of  machinery  increases  as  well  as  simplifies  production,  and  here, 
surely,  is  sufficient  gain  for  the  employer  and  the  purchaser,  without  trenching 
upon  the  wage  of  the  worker,  whose  needs  remain  the  same  whether  tending  a 
machine  or  using  his  tools  by  hand.  Upon  this  ground  we  base  our  claim,  but, 
convinced  as  we  are  that  this,  like  most  other  questions,  must  ultimately  be 
settled  in  accord  with  the  common  interest,  and  believing  as  we  do  in  the  wisdom 
contained  in  the  utterance  of  the  late  Lord  Derby  that  '  the  greatest  of  all  interests 
is  peace,'  we  are  willing  to  leave  the  matter  to  the  arbitrament  of  a  public  and 
impartial  authority,  aided  by  technical  knowledge  from  each  side." — Amalgamated 
Society  of  Engineers,  Forty-Sixth  Annual  Report  (London,  1897),  pp.  vi.-vii. 


824  Trade  Union  Theory 

Should  capitalism  develop  in  the  direction  of  gigantic  Trusts, 
the  organisation  of  the  manual  workers  in  each  industry  will 
be  the  only  effective  bulwark  against  social  oppression.  If, 
on  the  other  hand,  there  should  be  a  revival  of  the  small 
master  system,  the  enforcement  of  Common  Rules  will  be 
more  than  ever  needed  to  protect  the  community  against 
industrial  parasitism.1  And  if,  as  we  personally  expect, 
democracy  moves  in  the  direction  of  superseding  both  the 
little  profit-maker  and  the  Trust,  by  the  salaried  officer  of 
the  Co-operative  Society,  the  Municipality,  and  the  Govern- 
ment Department,  Trade  Unionism  would  remain  equally 
necessary.  For  even  under  the  most  complete  Collectivism, 
the  directors  of  each  particular  industry  would,  as  agents  of 
the  community  of  consumers,  remain  biassed  in  favor  of 
cheapening  production,  and  could,  as  brainworkers,  never  be 
personally  conscious  of  the  conditions  of  the  manual  laborers. 
And  though  it  may  be  assumed  that  the  community  as  a 
whole  would  not  deliberately  oppress  any  section  of  its 
members,  experience  of  all  administration  on  a  large  scale, 
whether  public  or  private,  indicates  how  difficult  it  must 
always  be,  in  any  complicated  organisation,  for  an  isolated 
individual  sufferer  to  obtain  redress  against  the  malice,  caprice, 
or  simple  heedlessness  of  his  official  superior.  Even  a  whole 
class  or  grade  of  workers  would  find  it  practically  impossible, 
without  forming  some  sort  of  association  of  its  own,  to  bring 
its  special  needs  to  the  notice  of  public  opinion,  and  press 
them  effectively  upon  the  Parliament  of  the  nation.  More- 
over, without  an  organisation  of  each  grade  or  section  of 
the  producers,  it  would  be  difficult  to  ensure  the  special 
adaptation  to  their  particular  conditions  of  the  National 
Minimum,  or  other  embodiment  of  the  Doctrine  of  a  Living 
Wage,  which  the  community  would  need  to  enforce  ;  and  it 
would  be  impossible  to  have  that  progressive  and  experi- 
mental pressing  upward  of  the  particular  Common  Rules  of 
each  class,  upon  which,  as  we  have  seen,  the  maximum 
productivity  of  the  nation  depends.  In  short,  it  is  essential 

1  See  Part  II.  chap.  xii.  "The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism." 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  825 

that  each  grade  or  section  of  producers  should  be  at  least  so 
well  organised  that  it  can  compel  public  opinion  to  listen  to 
its  claims,  and  so  strongly  combined  that  it  could  if  need 
be,  as  a  last  resort  against  bureaucratic  stupidity  or  official 
oppression,  enforce  its  demands  by  a  concerted  abstention 
from  work,  against  every  authority  short  of  a  decision  of  the 
public  tribunals,  or  a  deliberate  judgment  of  the  Representative 
Assembly  itself. 

But  though,  as  industry  passes  more  and  more  into 
public  control,  Trade  Unionism  must  still  remain  a  necessary 
element  in  the  democratic  state,  it  would,  we  conceive,  in 
such  a  development,  undergo  certain  changes.  The  mere 
extension  of  national  agreements  and  factory  legislation  has 
already,  in  the  most  highly  regulated  trades,  superseded  the 
old  guerilla  warfare  between  employers  and  employed,  and 
transformed  the  Trade  Union  official  from  a  local  strike 
leader  to  an  expert  industrial  negotiator,  mainly  occupied, 
with  the  cordial  co-operation  of  the  secretary  of  the  Employers' 
Association  and  the  Factory  Inspector,  in  securing  an  exact 
observance  of  the  Common  Rules  prescribed  for  the  trade. 
And  as  each  part  of  the  minimum  conditions  of  employment 
becomes  definitely  enacted  in  the  regulations  governing  the 
public  industries,  or  embodied  in  the  law  of  the  land,  it  will 
tend  more  and  more  to  be  accepted  by  the  directors  of 
industry  as  a  matter  of  course,  and  will  need  less  and  less 
enforcement  by  the  watchful  officials  concerned.1  The  Trade 
Union  function  of  constantly  maintaining  an  armed  resistance 
to  attempts  to  lower  the  Standard  of  Life  of  its  members 
may  be  accordingly  expected  to  engage  a  diminishing  share 
of  its  attention.  On  the  other  hand,  its  duty  of  perpetually 
striving  to  raise  the  level  of  its  Common  Rules,  and  thereby 
increasing  the  specialised  technical  efficiency  of  its  craft,  will 
remain  unabated.  We  may  therefore  expect  that,  with  the 
progressive  nationalisation  or  rnunicipalisation  of  public 
services,  on  the  one  hand,  and  the  spread  of  the  Co-operative 
movement  on  the  other,  the  Trade  Unions  of  the  workers 

1  See  Tart  II.  chap.  iv.  "The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment." 


826  Trade  Union  Theory 

thus  taken  directly  into  the  employment  of  the  citizen- 
consumers  will  more  and  more  assume  the  character  of 
professional  associations.  Like  the  National  Union  of 
Teachers  at  the  present  day,  they  may  even  come  to  be 
little  concerned  with  any  direct  bargaining  as  to  sanitation, 
hours,  or  wages,  except  by  way  of  redressing  individual 
grievances,  or  supplying  expert  knowledge  as  to  the  effect 
of  proposed  changes.  The  conditions  of  employment  depend- 
ing on  the  degree  of  expert  specialisation  to  which  the  craft 
has  been  carried,  and  upon  public  opinion  as  to  its  needs, 
each  Trade  Union  will  find  itself,  like  the  National  Union 
of  Teachers,  more  and  more  concerned  with  raising  the 
standard  of  competency  in  its  occupation,  improving  the 
professional  equipment  of  its  members,  "educating  their 
masters "  as  to  the  best  way  of  carrying  on  the  craft,  and 
endeavoring  by  every  means  to  increase  its  status  in  public 
estimation.1 

So  far  our  review  of  the  functions  of  Trade  Unionism  in 
the  democratic  state  has  taken  account  only  of  its  part  in 
industrial  organisation.  But  the  Trade  Unions  are  turned 
also  to  other  uses.  At  present,  for  instance,  they  compete 
with  the  ordinary  friendly  societies  and  industrial  insurance 
companies  in  providing  money  benefits  in  cases  of  accident, 
sickness,  and  death,  together  with  pensions  for  the  aged.2 
This  is  the  side  of  Trade  Unionism  which  commonly  meets 
with  the  greatest  approval,  but  it  is  a  side  that,  in  our 
opinion,  is  destined  to  dwindle.  As  one  class  of  invalids 
after  another  is  taken  directly  under  public  care,  the  friendly 
benefits  provided  by  the  Trade  Unions  will  no  longer  be 
necessary  to  save  their  members  from  absolute  destitution. 

1  The  industry  with  which  the  National   Union  of  Teachers  is  mainly  con- 
cerned— elementary  school-keeping — has,  within  a  couple  of  generations,  entirely 
passed  out  of  the  domain  of  profit-making  into  that  of  a  public  service.     The 
Union  (established  1870,  membership  at  end  of  1896,  36,793)  has  thus  grown  up 
under  a  Collectivist  organisation,  and  a  comparison  between  its  functions  and  those 
of  the  manual  workers'  Trade  Unions  is  full  of  interest  and  significance.     Its 
admirably  compiled  and  elaborate  Annual  Reports  afford  constant  illustrations 
of  the  above  inferences. 

2  See  Part  II.  chap.  i.  "The  Method  of  Mutual  Insurance." 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  827 

With  any  general  system  of  compensation  for  industrial 
accidents,  provided  or  secured  by  the  state  itself,  the  costly 
"  accident  benefit "  hitherto  given  by  Trade  Unions  will 
become  a  thing  of  the  past.  The  increasing  use  in  sickness 
of  hospitals  and  convalescent  homes,  the  growing  importance 
of  isolation  and  skilled  nursing,  and  the  gratuitous  provision 
in  public  institutions  of  the  highest  medical  skill — adopted 
for  reasons  of  public  health — will  incidentally  go  far  to 
relieve  working-class  families  of  the  intolerable  strain  of 
periods  of  bodily  incapacity.1  Any  Government  scheme  of 
Old  Age  Pensions,  such,  for  instance,  as  that  proposed  by 
Mr.  Charles  Booth,  would  absolve  the  Trade  Unions  from 
their  present  attempts,  in  the  form  of  superannuation  benefit, 
to  buy  off  the  undercutting  of  the  Standard  Rate  of  wages 
by  their  aged  members.  It  is  not  that  State  provision 
against  the  absolute  destitution  caused  by  accident,  sickness, 
or  old  age,  will  supersede,  or  even  diminish,  individual  saving. 
On  the  contrary,  it  is  one  of  the  grounds  on  which  Mr. 
Charles  Booth  and  others  advocate  these  measures,2  that  the 
state  pension,  by  ensuring  something  to  build  on,  will  positively 
stimulate  thrift.  But  this  supplementary  saving,  to  provide 
the  little  comforts  and  amenities  beyond  the  state  allowance, 
will,  in  our  opinion,  not  be  made  through  the  Trade  Union. 
As  the  manual  workers  advance  in  intelligence  and  foresight, 

1  There  is  no  reason  why  the  burial  of  the  dead   should  not — to   the   great 
economic  advantage  of  all  concerned — become  a  public  service  and  a  common 
charge.      Probably  a  majority  of  all  the  funerals  in  the  United  Kingdom  already 
take  place  at  the  public  expense,  and  the  provision   of  burial  grounds,   once   a 
common  form  of  profit-making  enterprise,  is  becoming  almost  exclusively  a  public 
function.      In  Paris,  as  is   well  known,   the  service  of  burial  is  performed  by 
a   strictly    regulated  and   licensed  monopolist   corporation,    virtually   public  in 
character. 

2  On  Old  Age  Pensions,  see  "The  Reform  of  the   Poor   Law,"   by   Sidney 
Webb  in  Contemporary  Review,  July  1890,  republished  as  Fabian  Tract  No.  17, 
March  1891;  the  paper  on   "Enumeration   and   Classification   of  Paupers,   and 
State  Pensions  for  the  Aged,"  by  Charles  Booth,  read  before  the  Statistical  Society, 
December  1891,  and  republished  as  Pauperism,  a  Picture  and  Endowment  of  Old 
Age,  an  Argument  (London,  1892) ;  and  Pensions  and  Pauperism,  by  the  Rev. 
J.  Frome  Wilkinson  (London,    1892).     These  proposals  must  be  distinguished 
from  schemes  of  insurance,  or  making  the  poor  provide  their  own  pension,  as  to 
which  see  Part  II.  chap.  xii.  "The  Implications  of  Trade  Unionism." 


828  Trade  Union  Theory 

they  will  more  and  more  realise  that  a  Trade  Union,  how- 
ever honestly  and  efficiently  administered,  is,  of  necessity, 
financially  unsound  as  a  friendly  society.  Hitherto  the 
actuarial  defects  of  the  friendly  society  side  of  Trade 
Unionism  have  been  far  outweighed  by  the  adventitious 
advantages  which  it  brought  to  the  organisation  in  attract- 
ing recruits,  rolling  up  a  great  reserve  fund,  and  ensuring 
discipline.  But  in  the  democratic  state  these  adventitious 
aids  will  no  longer  be  necessary.  The  Trade  Union  will  be 
a  definitely  recognised  institution  of  public  utility  to  which 
every  person  working  at  the  craft  will  be  imperatively  ex- 
pected, even  if  not  (as  is  already  the  case  with  regard  to  the 
appointment  of  a  checkweigher),1  legally  compelled  to  con- 
tribute. With  Trade  Union  membership  thus  virtually  or 
actually  compulsory,  Trade  Union  leaders  will  find  it  con- 
venient to  concentrate  their  whole  attention  on  the  funda- 
mental purposes  of  their  organisation,  and  to  cede  the  mere 
insurance  business  to  the  Friendly  Societies.  Thus,  with  the 
complete  recognition  of  Trade  Unionism  as  an  essential 
organ  of  the  democratic  state,  the  Friendly  Societies  and 
Mutual  Insurance  Companies,  confining  themselves  to  the 
co-operative  provision  of  larger  opportunities  and  additional 
amenities  to  the  aged,  sick,  or  injured  workman,  will  be 
relieved  from  the  competition  of  actuarially  defective  trade 
societies,  and  may  therefore  be  expected  to  expand  and  con- 
solidate their  own  position  as  an  indispensable  part  of  social 
organisation. 

To  this  decay  of  the  friendly  society  side  of  Trade 
Unionism  there  will  probably  be  one  exception.  In  the 
democratic  state  the  evil  effects  of  the  alternate  expansions 
and  contractions  of  demand  will  doubtless  be  mitigated  by 
the  increasing  regulation  and  concentration  of  industry,  if 
not  also,  as  some  would  say,  by  the  substitution,  for  the 
speculative  middleman,  of  the  salaried  official  of  the  con- 
sumers. But  the  inevitable  fluctuations  in  the  consumers' 

1  See  Part  IT.  chap.  ii.  "The  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining,"  and  chap.  v. 
"The  Standard  Rate." 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  829 

own  tastes,  together  with  the  vicissitudes  ol  harvests,  will 
at  all  times  leave  some  workmen  in  some  trades  or  in 
some  districts  temporarily  unemployed.  Hence  the  Out  of 
Work  Benefit,  or  Donation,  will  form  a  permanent  feature  of 
the  democratic  state.  This  provision  for  temporarily  un- 
employed craftsmen, — to  be  carefully  distinguished  from 
persons  falling  below  the  standard  of  the  National  Minimum, 
or  the  unemployable — can,  as  we  have  suggested,  be  best 
administered  by  the  Trade  Union.  Even  when,  as  in  times 
of  severe  depression,  or  in  cases  of  supersession  by  a  new 
invention,  some  assistance  of  the  temporarily  unemployed  is 
given  from  public  funds,  it  will  probably  be  most  economical 
for  it  to  take  the  form  of  a  capitation  grant  to  the  Trade 
Union,  so  calculated  that  the  allowance  to  each  unemployed 
member  is  shared  between  the  government  and  the  dis- 
tributing association. 

But  whilst  Trade  Unionism  may  be  expected  to  lose 
some  of  its  present  incidental  functions,  we  suggest  that 
the  democratic  state  will  probably  find  it  new  duties  to 
fulfil.  For  most  of  the  purposes  of  government,  including 
registration,  taxation,  the  general  education  of  the  young, 
and  the  election  of  representatives,  the  classification  of  the 
citizens  into  geographical  districts  according  to  their  place 
of  abode  is,  no  doubt,  the  most  convenient  form.  But  there 
are  other  purposes  for  which  the  geographical  organisation 
may  usefully  be  supplemented  by  an  organisation  according 
to  professional  occupations.  The  technical  instruction  of 
our  craftsmen  would,  for  instance,  gain  enormously  in  vigor 
and  reality  if  the  Trade  Unions  were  in  some  way  directly 
associated  with  the  administration  of  the  technological 
classes  relating  to  their  particular  trades.  Even  now  Trade 
Union  committees  sometimes  render  admirable  service  by 
watchful  supervision  of  trade  classes,  by  suggestion  and 
criticism,  and  by  practically  requiring  their  apprentices  to 
attend.  And  once  it  becomes  clearly  understood  all  round 
that  the  object  of  Technical  Education  is  not,  by  increasing 
the  number  of  craftsmen,  to  lower  wages,  but,  by  increasing 


830  Trade  Union  Theory 

the  competence  of  those  who  have  already  entered  the  various 
trades,  positively  to  raise  their  Standard  of  Life,  the  Trade 
Unions  and  the  community  as  a  whole  will  be  seen  to  have 
an  identical  interest  in  the  matter.  There  is,  in  fact,  no 
reason  why  a  Trade  Union  should  not  be  treated  as  a 
local  administrative  committee  of  the  Technical  Education 
Authority,  and  allowed,  under  proper  supervision,  to  conduct 
its  own  technological  classes  with  public  funds.1  In  other 
directions,  too,  such  as  the  compilation  of  statistics  relating 
to  particular  occupations,  and  the  dissemination  of  informa- 
tion useful  to  members  of  particular  crafts,  the  democratic 
state  will  probably  make  increasing  use  of  Trade  Union 
machinery. 

Finally,  there  is  the  service  of  counsel.  On  all  issues  of 
industrial  regulation,  whether  in  their  own  or  other  trades, 
the  Trade  Union  officials  will  naturally  assume  the  position 
of  technical  experts,  to  whom  public  opinion  will  look  for 
guidance.  But  industrial  regulation  is  not  the  only  matter 
on  which  a  democratic  state  needs  the  counsels  of  a  work- 
ing-class organisation.  Whenever  a  proposal  or  a  scheme 
touches  the  daily  life  of  the  manual -working  wage -earner, 
the  representative  committees  and  experienced  officials  of  the 
Trade  Union  world  are  in  a  position  to  contribute  informa- 
tion and  criticism,  which  are  beyond  the  reach  of  any  other 
class.  They  are,  of  course,  ignorant,  if  not  incapable,  of  the 
complications  and  subtilties  of  the  law.  Their  suggestions 
are  one-sided  and  often  impracticable,  and  their  opinion  can 
never  be  accepted  as  decisive.  But  whenever  a  minister 
has  to  deal  with  such  questions  as  the  Housing  of  the  People 
or  the  Regulation  of  the  Liquor  Traffic,  the  administration 
of  the  law  by  magistrates  or  county-court  judges,  the  un- 

1  There  seems  much  to  be  said  for  combining  trade  classes  with  the  provision 
for  the  temporarily  unemployed.  A  large  proportion  of  the  unemployed  printers, 
for  instance,  who  hang  about  the  office  of  the  London  Society  of  Compositors 
waiting  for  a  "call"  from  an  employer,  are  very  indifferent  workmen,  often 
young  men  who  have  "picked  up"  the  trade  without  any  really  educational 
apprenticeship.  There  would  be  much  advantage  if  their  Out  of  Work  Donation 
were  made  conditional  on  their  spending  the  idle  time  in  perfecting  themselves  at 
their  craft. 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  83 1 

employed  or  the  unemployable,  the  working  of  the  Education 
Acts  and  the  Poor  Law,  or,  to  pass  into  quite  another 
department  of  the  public  service,  the  organisation  of 
popular  recreation  and  amusement,  he  will  find  himself 
obliged,  if  he  wishes  to  make  his  legislation  or  administra- 
tion genuinely  successful,  to  discover  the  desires  and  needs 
of  the  manual  workers,  as  represented  by  the  committees 
and  officials  whom  they  elect. 

This  examination  of  the  function  of  Trade  Unionism 
brings  us  face  to  face  with  its  inherent  limitations.  Trade 
Unionism,  to  begin  with,  does  not  furnish  any  complete 
scheme  of  distribution  of  the  community's  income.  The 
Device  of  the  Common  Rule,  can,  by  its  very  nature,  never 
reach  any  other  part  of  the  product  than  the  minimum 
applicable  to  the  worst  as  well  as  to  the  best  establishment 
for  the  time  being  in  use.  It  leaves  untouched,  as  we  have 
shown,1  all  that  large  proportion  of  the  aggregate  income 
which  is  the  equivalent  of  the  differential  advantages  of  the 
various  factors  of  production  above  the  marginal  level, 
whether  their  superiority  lies  in  soil  or  site,  machinery  or 
organisation,  intellect  or  physical  strength.  In  short,  as 
between  different  localities,  different  establishments,  or 
different  individuals,  Trade  Unionism  leaves  unaffected 
everything  in  the  nature  of  economic  rent.  And  even  if  we 
imagine  each  branch  of  productive  industry  throughout  the 
community  to  be  amalgamated  into  a  single  capitalist  trust 
or  government  department,  each  grade  or  section  of  manual 
workers  would  find  itself  receiving,  not  an  aliquot  part  of  the 
total  produce,  but  a  wage  depending  either  on  the  minimum 
necessary  for  the  efficient  fulfilment  of  its  particular  function, 
or,  for  all  the  grades  above  the  National  Minimum,  upon  the 
degree  of  technical  specialisation,  and  therefore  of  relative 
scarcity,  to  which  it  had  brought  its  particular  service.  The 
disposal  of  the  balance  of  the  product — the  administration, 
that  is  to  say,  of  the  rent  of  land  and  capital — must,  under 

1  Part  III.  chap.  iii.    "The  Economic  Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism," 
under  the  heading  "The  Device  of  the  Common  Rule." 


832  Trade  Union  Theory 

any  system  of  society,  fall    to   the   owners    of  the   material 
instruments  of  production. 

Now,  Trade  Unionism  has  no  logical  connection  with 
any  particular  form  of  ownership  of  land  and  capital,  and 
the  members  of  British  Trade  Unions  are  not  drawn,  as 
Trade  Unionists,  unreservedly  either  towards  Individualism 
or  towards  Collectivism.  Certain  sections  of  the  Trade 
Union  world,  as  we  have  pointed  out  in  our  chapter  on  "  The 
Implications  of  Trade  Unionism,"  1  find  that  they  can  exact 
better  terms  from  the  capitalist  employer  than  would  be 
likely  to  be  conceded  to  them  by  a  democratic  government 
department.  Other  sections,  on  the  contrary,  see  in  the 
extension  of  public  employment  the  only  remedy  for  a 
disastrous  irregularity  of  work  and  all  the  evils  of  sweating. 
This  divergence  of  immediate  interests  between  different 
sections  of  producers  will  inevitably  continue.  But  the 
nationalisation  or  municipalisation  of  any  industry — the 
taking  over  of  the  telephones,  ocean  cables,  railways,  or  mines 
by  the  central  government,  or  the  administration  of  slaughter- 
houses, tramways,  river  steamboats,  or  public-houses  by  the 
Town  Council — has  to  be  determined  on  wider  issues  than 
the  sectional  interests  of  the  wage-earners  employed.  It  is 
in  their  capacity  of  citizens,  not  as  Trade  Unionists,  that  the 
manual  workers  will  have  to  decide  between  the  rival  forms 
of  social  organisation,  and  to  make  up  their  minds  as  to  how 
they  wish  the  economic  rent  of  the  nation's  land  and  capital 
to  be  distributed.  And  though,  in  this,  the  most  momentous 
issue  of  modern  democracy,  the  manual  workers  will  be 
influenced  by  their  poverty  in  favor  of  a  more  equal  sharing 
of  the  benefits  of  combined  labor,2  they  will,  by  their  Trade 
Unionism,  not  be  biassed  in  favor  of  any  particular  scheme  of 
attaining  this  result  outside  their  own  Device  of  the  Common 
Rule.  And  when  we  pass  from  the  ownership  of  the  means 

1  Part  II.  chap.  xii. 

2  "  The  social  problem  of  the  future  we  considered  to  be,  how  to  unite  the 
greatest  individual  liberty  of  action  with  a  common  ownership  in  the  raw  material 
of  the  globe,  and  an  equal  participation  of  all  in  the  benefits  of  combined  labor.'1' — • 
John  Stuart  Mill,  Autobiography  (London,  1879),  p.  232. 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  833 

of  production  and  the  administration  of  industry  to  such 
practical  problems  as  the  best  form  of  currency  or  the  proper 
relation  between  local  and  central  government,  or  to  such 
vital  questions  as  the  collective  organisation  of  moral  and 
religious  teaching,  the  provision  for  scholarship  and  science 
and  the  promotion  of  the  arts — not  to  mention  the 
sharper  issues  of  "  Home  Rule "  or  foreign  affairs — the 
members  of  the  Trade  Union  world  have  no  distinctive 
opinion,  and  their  representatives  and  officials  no  special 
knowledge.  We  may  therefore  infer  that  the  wage-earners 
will,  in  the  democratic  state,  not  content  themselves  with 
belonging  to  their  Trade  Union,  or  even  to  any  wider 
organisation  based  on  a  distinction  of  economic  class. 
Besides  their  distinctive  interests  and  opinions  as  wage- 
earners  and  manual  workers,  they  have  others  which  they 
share  with  persons  of  every  grade  or  occupation.  The 
citizen  in  the  democratic  state,  enrolled  first  in  his 
geographical  constituency,  will  take  his  place  also  in  the 
professional  association  of  his  craft  ;  but  he  will  go  on  to 
combine  in  voluntary  associations  for  special  purposes  with 
those  who  agree  with  him  in  religion  or  politics,  or  in  the 
pursuit  of  particular  recreations  or  hobbies. 

These  considerations  have  a  direct  bearing  on  the 
probable  development  of  Trade  Union  structure.  In 
the  first  part  of  this  work  we  described 1  how,  in  spite 
of  historical  tradition,  in  spite  of  crude  ideas  of  de- 
mocracy suited  only  to  little  autonomous  communities, 
and  in  spite  of  a  strong  prejudice  in  favor  of  local 
exclusiveness,  the  Trade  Union  world  has,  throughout  its 
whole  history,  manifested  an  overpowering  impulse  to  the 
amalgamation  of  local  trade  clubs  into  national  unions,  with 
centralised  funds  and  centralised  administration.  The 
economic  characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism  revealed  to  us 
the  source  of  this  impulse  in  the  fundamental  importance  to 
each  separate  class  of  operatives  that  its  occupation  should 

1  Part    I.    chap.    i.     "  Primitive    Democracy,"    chap.    ii.     "  Representative 
Institutions,"  chap.  iii.  "The  Unit  of  Government." 

VOL.  II  3  IT 


834  Trade  Union  Theory 

be  governed  by  its  own  Common  Rules,  applicable  from  one 
end  of  the  kingdom  to  the  other.  This  centralisation  of 
administration,  involving  the  adoption  of  a  national  trade 
policy,  and,  above  all,  the  constant  levelling-up  of  the  lower- 
paid  districts  to  the  higher  standard  set  in  more  advantageous 
centres,  requires,  it  is  clear,  the  development  of  a  salaried 
staff,  selected  for  special  capacity,  devoting  their  whole 
attention  to  the  commercial  position  and  technical  details 
of  the  particular  section  of  the  industry  that  they  represent, 
and  able  to  act  for  the  whole  of  that  section  throughout  the 
nation.  It  is,  as  we  saw  in  our  chapter  on  "  The  Method  of 
Collective  Bargaining,"  l  because  of  the  absence  of  such  a  staff 
that  so  few  of  the  Trade  Unions  of  the  present  day  secure 
national  agreements,  or  enforce  with  uniformity  such  Common 
Rules  as  they  obtain.  The  Trade  Union  of  the  future  will, 
therefore,  be  co-extensive  with  its  craft,  national  in  its  scope, 
centralised  in  its  administration,  and  served  by  an  expert 
official  staff  of  its  own. 

This  consolidation  of  authority  in  the  central  office  of  the 
national  union  for  each  craft  will  be  accompanied  by  an  in- 
creased activity  of  the  branches.  In  our  description  of  Trade 
Union  Structure,2  we  saw  that  the  crude  and  mechanical  expedi- 
ents of  the  Initiative  and  the  Referendum  were  being  steadily 
replaced,  for  all  the  more  complicated  issues  of  government,  by 
an  organic  differentiation  of  representative  institutions.  So 
long  as  a  union  was  contented  with  Government  by  Referendum 
all  that  was  necessary  was  an  ambulatory  ballot-box  by 
which  an  unemployed  member  collected  "  the  voices  "  of  each 
factory  or  each  pit.  When  a  representative  is  appointed,  the 
branch  meeting  affords  the  opportunity  for  ascertaining  the 
desires  of  his  constituents,  impressing  upon  them  his  own 
advice,  and  consulting  with  them  in  any  emergency.  The 
branch  thus  becomes  the  local  centre  of  the  union's  intellectual 
life.  At  the  same  time  it  retains  and  even  extends  its 

1  Part  II.  chap.  ii. 

2  Part  I.  chap.  i.    "Primitive  Democracy,"  and  chap.   ii.  "Representative 
Institutions." 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  835 

functions  as  a  jury  or  local  administrative  committee.  For 
even  if  the  Trade  Union  gradually  discards  its  purely 
"  friendly "  benefits,  the  branch  will  have  to  administer  the 
all-important  Out  of  Work  Donation,  supplemented,  as  this 
may  be,  by  a  grant  from  public  funds.  And  with  the 
increasing  use  which  the  democratic  state  may  make  of 
Trade  Union  machinery,  it  will  be  the  branch,  and  not  the 
central  office,  that  will  be  charged  with  conducting  technical 
classes,  collecting  statistics,  or  disseminating  information. 
Finally,  when  the  Trade  Union  world  desires  to  make  use 
of  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment,1  or  to  supervise  the  con- 
ditions of  employment  granted  by  local  governing  bodies, 
the  network  of  branches  pervading  every  district  affords,  as 
we  have  seen,  the  only  practicable  way  of  superposing  an 
organisation  by  constituencies  on  an  organisation  by  trades. 
There  is  one  direction  in  which  the  branch  (or,  in  the 
larger  centres,  the  district  committee  representing  several 
branches)  will  find  this  increase  of  work  accompanied  by 
a  decrease  of  autonomy.  The  central  executive  and  the 
salaried  officials  at  the  head  office  of  each  craft  will  be 
principally  occupied  in  securing  national  minimum  conditions 
of  employment  throughout  the  country.  It  will  be  for  the 
branches  and  their  district  committees  to  be  constantly  con- 
sidering the  particular  needs  and  special  opportunities  of 
their  own  localities.  But  the  fact  that  the  cost  of  any 
"  advance  movement "  falls  upon  the  funds  of  the  union  as 
a  whole  makes  it  imperative  that  no  dispute  should  be 
begun,  and  even  that  no  claim  should  be  made,  until  the 
position  has  been  carefully  considered  by  the  central  ex- 
ecutive representing  the  whole  society.  This  precept  of 
democratic  finance  is  made  more  imperative  by  every  con- 
solidation of  the  forces  of  capital.  It  is  obvious  that  if  the 
demand  of  the  branches  in  one  town  for  an  advance  of 
wages  or  reduction  of  hours  is  liable  to  be  met  by  a  lock- 
out of  the  whole  trade  throughout  the  country,  a  union 
which  permits  its  local  branches  to  involve  it  in  war  at 

1  See  Part  II.  chap.  iv.  "The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment." 


836  Trade  Union  Theory 

their  own  uncontrolled  discretion  simply  courts  disaster. 
In  matters  of  trade  policy  the  branches  or  district  com- 
mittees, whilst  undertaking  even  more  of  the  work  of 
supervision,  local  interpretation,  and  suggestion,  must  de- 
finitely give  up  all  claim  to  autonomy.1 

The  need  for  centralisation  of  authority,  as  an  in- 
evitable consequence  of  centralisation  of  funds,  is  not  the 
only  lesson  in  structure  that  the  Trade  Unions  have  derived 
from  their  experience,  or  will  learn  as  they  realise  their  full 
function  in  the  democratic  state.  In  our  chapter  on  "  Inter- 
Union  Relations  " 2  we  pointed  out  that  the  amalgamation  of 
different  sections  into  a  single  society  may  easily  be  carried 
too  far.  The  formation  of  a  central  fund,  filled  by  equal 
contributions  from  all  the  members,  inevitably  leads  to 
equality  of  franchise  and  government  by  the  numerical 
majority.  So  long  as  the  interests  of  all  the  members  are 
fairly  identical,  this  majority  rule,  where  efficient  representa- 
tive machinery  has  been  developed,  is  the  most  feasible 
contrivance  for  uniting  administrative  efficiency  with  popular 
control.  But  whenever  the  association  contains  several 
distinct  classes  of  workers,  having  different  degrees  of  skill, 
divergent  standards  of  expenditure,  and  varying  needs  and 
opportunities,  experience  shows  that  any  scheme  of  equalised 
finance  and  centralised  administration  produces,  even  with 
the  best  democratic  machinery,  neither  efficiency  nor  the 
consciousness  of  popular  control,  and  hence  is  always  in  a 
condition  of  unstable  equilibrium.  The  several  minorities, 
keenly  alive  to  their  separate  requirements  and  opportunities, 
are  always  feeling  themselves  thwarted  in  pushing  their  own 
interests,  and  deprived  of  any  effective  control  over  the  con- 
ditions of  their  own  lives.  In  voluntary  associations  the 
result  is  a  perpetual  tendency  to  secession,  each  distinct 
section  aiming  at  Home  Rule  by  setting  up  for  itself  as 
a  separate  national  union.  This  limitation  on  the  process 
of  amalgamation,  arising  out  of  the  conditions  of  democratic 

1   See  Part  I.  chap.  iii.  "The  Unit  of  Government." 
2  Part  I.  chap.  iv. 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  837 

structure,  is  fortified,  as  we  can  now  see,  by  economic  con- 
siderations.1 The  largest  income  for  the  wage-earners,  and 
the  highest  efficiency  of  industry,  will,  as  we  have  pointed 
out,  be  secured  not  by  any  uniform  wage  for  manual  labor 
as  such,  or  for  all  the  operatives  in  any  industry,  but  by 
each  distinct  section  of  workers  using  the  Device  of  the 
Common  Rule  to  raise  to  the  utmost  its  own  conditions  of 
employment.  This  persistent  pushing  forward  of  each  class 
of  operatives,  constantly  imperilled,  as  it  must  be,  by  a  rise 
in  the  price  of  the  product  and  a  diminution  of  demand  for 
some  particular  section  of  labor,  can  be  undertaken,  it  will 
be  obvious,  only  at  the  risk  and  cost  of  that  section,  and 
therefore,  in  practice,  on  its  own  initiative,  untrammelled  by 
the  votes  of  other  sections.  We  may  therefore  expect,  in 
the  democratic  state,  not  a  single  association  of  the  whole 
wage-earning  class,  nor  yet  a  single  amalgamated  union  for 
each  great  industry,  but  separate  organisations  for  such  of 
the  various  sections  of  producers  as  are  so  far  specialised 
from  others  as  to  possess  and  require  separate  Common 
Rules  of  their  own. 

These  separate  national  organisations  will,  however, 
clearly  have  many  interests  in  common.  In  such  matters  as 
cubic  space,  ventilation,  temperature,  sanitary  conveniences, 
precautions  against  fire,  fencing  of  machinery,  and,  last  but 
by  no  means  least,  the  fixing  and  distribution  of  the  Normal 
Day,  the  conditions  of  employment  must,  in  the  majority  of 
manufacturing  industries,  be  identical  for  all  the  grades  of 
labor  in  each  establishment.  Even  for  Collective  Bargain- 
ing they  must  necessarily  develop  some  federal  machinery 
for  concerting  identical  demands  upon  their  common  em- 
ployers, and  for  supporting  them  by  joint  action.  Moreover, 
as  we  have  pointed  out,  in  all  questions  of  this  sort,  the 
democratic  state  will  be  influenced  in  the  main  by  the 
Doctrine  of  a  Living  Wage,  and  they  will  accordingly  tend 
more  and  more  to  be  settled  on  physiological  grounds  and  en- 
forced by  the  Method  of  Legal  Enactment.  It  is  unnecessary 

1  Part  III.  chap.  iii.  "  The  Economic  Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism." 


838  Trade  Union  Theory 

to  repeat  that  for  any  effective  use  of  this  Method  in  a  Parlia- 
mentary community,  organisation  by  crafts  is  practically  use- 
less, unless  it  is  supplemented  by  a  geographical  organisation 
by  constituencies.  Hence  we  see  rising  in  the  Trade  Union 
world  not  only  federal  action  among  groups  employed  in  one 
establishment,  such  as  the  joint  committees  of  the  building 
trades,  but  also  such  political  federations  as  the  United 
Textile  Factory  Workers'  Association,  the  local  Trades 
Councils,  and  the  Trade  Union  Congress.  But  the  economic 
analysis  of  the  Common  Rule  has  shown  us  that  there  is  a 
third,  and  even  more  important,  reason  for  this  federal  action 
between  different  trades.  It  will,  as  we  have  seen,  be  a 
primary  duty  of  the  Trade  Unions  in  the  democratic  state 
to  maintain  and  progressively  to  raise,  not  their  own  Com- 
mon Rules  alone,  but  also  the  National  Minimum  for  the 
whole  wage -earning  class.  To  the  national  amalgamation 
of  each  section,  and  the  federal  union  of  the  different 
sections  in  each  great  industry,  there  must  be  added  a 
federation  of  the  whole  Trade  Union  world. 

Our  vision  of  the  sphere  of  Trade  Unionism  in  the 
democratic  state  does  more  than  explain  the  development 
of  the  Trade  Union  world  into  a  hierarchy  of  federations. 
It  gives  us  also  its  political  programme.  The  weakness 
and  inefficiency  of  the  existing  Trades  Councils  and  Trade 
Union  Congress  spring,  as  we  have  pointed  out,  not  only 
from  their  extremely  imperfect  structure,  but  also  from  an 
entire  misapprehension  of  their  proper  function.1  In  spite 
of  the  fact  that  Trade  Unionists  include  men  of  all  shades 
of  political  opinion,  —  Conservatives  from  Lancashire, 
Liberals  from  Scotland,  Socialists  from  London  and  York- 
shire, —  the  federal  organisations  of  the  British  Trade 
Unions  of  to-day  are  perpetually  meddling  with  wide  issues 
of  general  politics,  upon  which  the  bulk  of  their  constituents 
have  either  no  opinions  at  all,  or  are  marshalled  in  the  ranks 
of  one  or  another  of  the  political  parties.  Resolutions 
abolishing  the  House  of  Lords,  secularising  education, 

1  See  Part  II.  chap,  iv,  "The  Method  of  Legal  Enactment." 


Trade  Un^nism  and  Democracy  839 

rehabilitating  silver,  establishing  a  system  of  peasant 
proprietorship,  enfranchising  leaseholds,  or  "  nationalising 
the  means  of  production,  distribution,  and  exchange," — 
questions  in  which  the  Trade  Unionists,  as  such,  are  not  more 
interested,  not  better  informed,  nor  yet  more  united  than 
other  citizens,  —  find  a  place  on  Trade  Union  agendas, 
and  either  get  formally  passed  through  sheer  indifference,  or 
become  the  source  of  discord,  recrimination,  and  disruption. 
This  waste  of  time  and  dissipation  of  energy  over  extraneous 
matters  arises,  we  think,  mainly  from  the  absence  of  any 
clearly  conceived  and  distinctive  Trade  Union  programme. 
In  the  democratic  state  of  the  future  the  Trade  Unionists 
may  be  expected  to  be  conscious  of  their  own  special 
function  in  the  political  world,  and  to  busy  themselves 
primarily  with  its  fulfilment.  First  in  importance  to  every 
section  we  put  the  establishment  of  a  National  Minimum  of 
education,  sanitation,  leisure,  and  wages,  its  application  to  all 
the  conditions  of  employment,  its  technical  interpretation  to 
fit  the  circumstances  of  each  particular  trade,  and,  above  all, 
its  vigorous  enforcement,  for  the  sake  of  the  whole  wage- 
earning  world,  in  the  weak  trades  no  less  than  in  those  more 
able  to  protect  themselves.  But  the  systematic  rehandling 
of  the  Factories  and  Workshops,  Mines,  Railways,  Shops,  and 
Merchant  Shipping  Acts,  which  is  involved  in  this  conception 
of  a  National  Minimum,  will,  as  we  have  explained,  only 
secure  the  base  of  the  pyramid.  Upon  this  fundamental 
ground  level  each  separate  craft  will  need  to  develop  such 
technical  regulations  of  its  own  as  are  required  to  remove  any 
conditions  of  employment  which  can  be  proved  to  be  actually 
prejudicial  to  the  efficiency  of  the  operatives  concerned.  On 
all  these  points,  as  we  have  seen,  the  claim  of  any  particular 
section  for  the  help  of  the  law  may  not  only  advantageously 
be  supported  by  all  the  other  trades,  but  may  also  profitably 
be  conceded  by  the  representatives  of  the  community.  And 
since  the  utmost  possible  use  of  the  Method  of  Legal  Enact- 
ment will,  as  we  have  seen,  still  permanently  leave  a  large 
sphere  for  the  Method  of  Collective  Bargaining,  there  must 


840  Trade  Union  Theory 

be  added  to  the  political  programme  of  the  federated  unions 
all  that  we  have  described  as  the  Implications  of  Trade 
Unionism.1  The  federal  executive  of  the  Trade  Union 
world  would  find  itself  defending  complete  freedom  of 
association,  and  carefully  watching  every  development  of 
legislation  or  judicial  interpretation  to  see  that  nothing  was 
made  criminal  or  actionable,  when  done  by  a  Trade  Union 
or  its  officials,  which  would  not  be  criminal  or  actionable 
if  done  by  a  partnership  of  traders  in  pursuit  of  their  own 
gain.  And  the  federal  executive  would  be  on  its  guard,  not 
only  against  a  direct  attack  on  the  workmen's  organisations, 
but  also  against  any  insidious  weakening  of  their  influence. 
It  would  insist  on  the  legal  prohibition  of  all  forms  of  truck, 
or  deductions  from  wages,  including  fines,  loom-rent,  and 
payments  to  national  insurance  funds  or  employers'  benefit 
societies.  Above  all,  it  would  resist  any  attempt  on  the  part 
of  the  employer  to  transform  the  workman's  home  into  a 
workshop,  and  thus  escape  the  responsibility  for  the  carrying 
out  of  the  conditions  of  employment  embodied  in  the  law  of 
the  land  With  a  programme  of  this  kind,  the  federal 
executive  would  find  itself  backed  by  the  whole  force  of  the 
Trade  Union  world,  which  would  thus  contribute  to  the 
councils  of  the  nation  that  technical  knowledge  and  specialist 
experience  of  manual  labor  without  which  the  regulation  of 
industry  can  become  neither  popular  nor  efficient. 

The  student  of  political  science  will  be  interested  in 
considering  what  light  the  experience  of  the  workmen's 
organisations  throws  upon  democracy  itself.  The  persistence 
of  Trade  Unionism,  and  its  growing  power  in  the  state, 
indicates,  to  begin  with,  that  the  very  conception  of 
democracy  will  have  to  be  widened,  so  as  to  include 
economic  as  well  as  political  relations.  The  framers  of  the 
United  States  constitution,  like  the  various  parties  in  the 
French  Revolution  of  1789,  saw  no  resemblance  or  analogy 
between  the  personal  power  which  they  drove  from  the 
castle,  the  altar,  and  the  throne,  and  that  which  they  left 

1  Part  II.  chap.  xii.  and  Appendix  I.  as  to  the  legal  position. 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  84 1 

unchecked  in  the  farm,  the  factory,  and  the  mine.  Even 
at  the  present  day,  after  a  century  of  revolution,  the  great 
mass  of  middle  and  upper-class  "  Liberals  "  all  over  the  world 
see  no  more  inconsistency  between  democracy  and  unre- 
strained capitalist  enterprise,  than  Washington  or  Jefferson 
did  between  democracy  and  slave -owning.  The  "  dim,  in- 
articulate" multitude  of  manual-working  wage-earners  have, 
from  the  outset,  felt  their  way  to  a  different  view.  To  them, 
the  uncontrolled  power  wielded  by  the  owners  of  the  means 
of  production,  able  to  withhold  from  the  manual  worker  all 
chance  of  subsistence  unless  he  accepted  their  terms,  meant 
a  far  more  genuine  loss  of  liberty,  and  a  far  keener  sense 
of  personal  subjection,  than  the  official  jurisdiction  of  the 
magistrate,  or  the  far-off,  impalpable  rule  of  the  king.  The 
captains  of  industry,  like  the  kings  of  yore,  are  honestly 
unable  to  understand  why  their  personal  power  should  be 
interfered  with,  and  kings  and  captains  alike  have  never 
found  any  difficulty  in  demonstrating  that  its  maintenance 
was  indispensable  to  society.  Against  this  autocracy  in 
industry,  the  manual  workers  have,  during  the  century, 
increasingly  made  good  their  protest.  The  agitation  for 
freedom  of  combination  and  factory  legislation  has  been,  in 
reality,  a  demand  for  a  "  constitution "  in  the  industrial 
realm.  The  tardy  recognition  of  Collective  Bargaining  and 
the  gradual  elaboration  of  a  Labor  Code  signifies  that  this 
Magna  Carta  will,  as  democracy  triumphs,  inevitably  be 
conceded  to  the  entire  wage-earning  class.  "  One  thing  is 
clear,"  wrote,  in  1869,  a  hostile  critic  ;  "  the  relation  between 
workmen  and  their  employers  has  permanently  changed  its 
character.  The  democratic  idea  which  rules  in  politics  has 
no  less  penetrated  into  industry.  The  notion  of  a  governing 
class,  exacting  implicit  obedience  from  inferiors,  and  im- 
posing upon  them  their  own  terms  of  service,  is  gone,  never 
to  return.  Henceforward,  employers  and  their  workmen 
must  meet  as  equals."  l  What  has  not  been  so  obvious  to 
middle -class  observers  is  the  necessary  condition  of  this 

1   Trade  Unionism,  by  James  Stirling  (Glasgow,  1869),  p.  55. 


842  Trade  Union  Theory 

equality.  Individual  Bargaining  between  the  owner  of  the 
means  of  subsistence  and  the  seller  of  so  perishable  a 
commodity  as  a  day's  labor  must  be,  once  for  all,  abandoned. 
In  its  place,  if  there  is  to  be  any  genuine  "  freedom  of 
contract,"  we  shall  see  the  conditions  of  employment 
adjusted  between  equally  expert  negotiators,  acting  for 
corporations  reasonably  comparable  in  strategic  strength, 
and  always  subject  to  and  supplemented  by  the  decisions  of 
the  High  Court  of  Parliament,  representing  the  interests  of 
the  community  as  a  whole.  Equality  in  industry  implies, 
in  short,  a  universal  application  of  the  Device  of  the 
Common  Rule.1 

Besides  the  imperative  lesson  that  political  democracy 
will  inevitably  result  in  industrial  democracy,  Trade 
Unionism  affords  some  indications  as  to  the  probable  work- 
ing of  democratic  institutions.  We  notice,  in  the  first  place, 
that  the  spontaneous  and  untrammelled  democracies  of  the 
workmen  show  neither  desire  for,  nor  tendency  to,  "  one  dead 
level  "  of  equality  of  remuneration  or  identity  of  service.  On 
the  contrary,  the  most  superficial  study  of  the  Trade  Union 
world  makes  the  old-fashioned  merging  of  all  the  manual 
workers  into  the  "  laboring  class  "  seem  almost  ludicrous  in 
its  ineptitude.  Instead  of  the  classic  economist's  categories 

1  We  attribute  to  an  imperfect  appreciation  of  the  change  of  status  many 
industrial  disputes,  and  a  large  proportion  of  the  resentment  of  working-class 
pretensions  manifested  by  the  brain  -  working  and  propertied  classes.  The 
employer  cannot  rid  himself  of  the  idea  that  he  has  bought  the  whole  energy  and 
capacity  of  the  operative  within  the  hours  of  the  working  day,  just  as  the  slave- 
owner had  bought  the  whole  capacity  of  his  slaves  for  life.  The  workman,  on 
the  other  hand,  regards  himself  as  hired  to  co-operate  in  industry  by  performing 
a  definite  task,  and  feels  himself  defrauded  if  the  employer  seeks  to  impose  upon 
him  any  extra  strain  or  discomfort,  or  any  different  duty,  not  specified  in  the 
bargain.  A  similar  misunderstanding  lingers  as  to  social  relations.  The 
capitalist  is  very  fond  of  declaring  that  labor  is  a  commodity,  and  the  wage 
contract  a  bargain  of  purchase  and  sale  like  any  other.  But  he  instinctively 
expects  his  wage-earners  to  render  him,  not  only  obedience,  but  also  personal 
deference.  If  the  wage  contract  is  a  bargain  of  purchase  and  sale  like  any 
other,  why  is  the  workman  expected  to  touch  his  hat  to  his  employer,  and  to 
say  "sir"  to  him  without  reciprocity,  when  the  employer  meets  on  terms  of 
equality  the  persons  (often  actually  of  higher  social  rank  than  himself)  from 
whom  he  buys  his  raw  material  or  makes  the  other  bargains  incidental  to  his 
trade  ? 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  843 

of  "  the  capitalist "  and  "  the  laborer,"  we  see  Trade  Unionism 
adopting  and  strengthening  the  almost  infinite  grading  of 
the  industrial  world  into  separate  classes,  each  with  its  own 
corporate  tradition  and  Standard  of  Life,  its  own  specialised 
faculty  and  distinctive  needs,  and  each  therefore  exacting  its 
own  "  Rent  of  Opportunity  "  or  "  Rent  of  Ability."  And 
when  we  examine  the  indirect  effect  of  the  Trade  Union 
Device  of  the  Common  Rule  in  extinguishing  the  Small 
Master  system  and  favoring  the  growth  of  the  Great 
Industry,1  we  realise  how  effectively  Trade  Unionism  extends 
a  similar  grading  to  the  brain-working  directors  of  industry. 
In  place  of  the  single  figure  of  the  "  capitalist  entrepreneur  "  we 
watch  emerging  in  each  trade  a  whole  hierarchy  of  specialised 
professionals,  —  inventors,  designers,  chemists,  engineers, 
buyers,  managers,  foremen,  and  what  not, — organised  in 
their  own  professional  associations,2  and  standing  midway 
between  the  shareholder,  taxpayer,  or  consumer,  whom  they 
serve,  and  the  graded  army  of  manual  workers  whom  they 
direct.  Nor  does  this  progressive  specialisation  of  function 
stop  at  economic  relations.  The  internal  development  of 
the  Trade  Union  world  unmistakably  indicates  that  division 
of  labor  must  be  carried  into  the  very  structure  of  democracy. 
Though  the  workmen  started  with  a  deeply-rooted  conviction 
that  "  one  man  was  as  good  as  another,"  and  that  democracy 
meant  an  "equal  and  identical  "  sharing  of  the  duties  of  govern- 
ment, as  well  as  of  its  advantages,  they  have  been  forced  to 
devolve  more  and  more  of  "  their  own  business  "on  a  specially 
selected  and  specially  trained  class  of  professional  experts. 
And  in  spite  of  the  almost  insuperable  difficulties  which 

1  Part  III.  chap.  iii.  "The  Economic  Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism." 

2  It  is  not  commonly  realised  how  numerous  and  how  varied  are  these  pro- 
fessional associations.       Besides  the   obvious  instances  01   the   three    "learned 
professions,"   organisations  of  this  kind  now  exist  among  all  grades    of  brain- 
workers  in  almost  every  department  of  social  life.     Not  to  speak  of  the  archi- 
tects, surveyors,  engineers,  actuaries,  and  accountants,  we  have  such  associations 
as  those  of  the  Gasworks  Managers,  Colliery  Managers,  School  Board  Clerks, 
Sanitary  Engineers,  Sanitary  Inspectors,  Medical  Officers  of  Health,  Inspectors 
of  Weights  and  Measures,  different  varieties  of  Foremen  and  Managers,  and  even 
Ships'  Clerks.     No  study  of  these  professional  associations,  or  of  their  extensive 
Common  Rules,  has  yet  been  ma.de. 


844  Trade  Union  Theory 

representative  institutions  present  to  a  community  of  un- 
leisured  manual  workers,  we  find  union  after  union  abandon- 
ing the  mechanical  devices  of  the  Referendum  and  the 
Initiative,  and  gradually  differentiating,  for  the  sake  of  the 
efficient  administration  of  its  own  affairs,  the  Representative 
from  the  Civil  Servant  on  the  one  hand  and  the  Elector  on 
the  other.  In  short,  whilst  Trade  Unionism  emphasises  the 
classic  dictum  of  Adam  Smith  that  division  of  labor  increases 
material  production,  it  carries  this  principle  into  the  organ- 
isation of  society  itself.  If  democracy  is  to  mean  the  com- 
bination of  administrative  efficiency  with  genuine  popular 
control,  Trade  Union  experience  points  clearly  to  an  ever- 
increasing  differentiation  between  the  functions  of  the  three 
indispensable  classes  of  Citizen-Electors,  chosen  Representa- 
tives, and  expert  Civil  Servants.1 

Thus  we  find  no  neat  formula  for  defining  the  rights  and 
duties  of  the  individual  in  society.  In  the  democratic  state 
every  individual  is  both  master  and  servant.  In  the  work 
that  he  does  for  the  community  in  return  for  his  subsistence 
he  is,  and  must  remain,  a  servant,  subject  to  the  instructions 
and  directions  of  those  whose  desires  he  is  helping  to  satisfy. 
As  a  Citizen-Elector  jointly  with  his  fellows,  and  as  a  Con- 
sumer to  the  extent  of  his  demand,  he  is  a  master,  determining, 
free  from  any  superior,  what  shall  be  done.  Hence,  it  is  the 
supreme  paradox  of  democracy  that  every  man  is  a  servant 
in  respect  of  the  matters  of  which  he  possesses  the  most 
intimate  knowledge,  and  for  which  he  shows  the  most  expert 
proficiency,  namely,  the  professional  craft  to  which  he  devotes 
his  working  hours  ;  and  he  is  a  master  over  that  on  which 
he  knows  no  more  than  anybody  else,  namely,  the  general 
interests  of  the  community  as  a  whole.  In  this  paradox,  we 
suggest,  lies  at  once  the  justification  and  the  strength  of 
democracy.  It  is  not,  as  is  commonly  asserted  by  the 
superficial,  that  Ignorance  rules  over  Knowledge,  and  Medio- 
crity over  Capacity.  In  the  administration  of  society  Know- 
ledge and  Capacity  can  make  no  real  and  durable  progress 
1  See  Part  I.  chaps,  i.  to  iv.  "Trade  Union  Structure," 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  845 

except  by  acting  on  and  through  the  minds  of  the  common 
human  material  which  it  is  desired  to  improve.  It  is  only 
by  carrying  along  with  him  the  "  average  sensual  man,"  that 
even  the  wisest  and  most  philanthropic  reformer,  however 
autocratic  his  power,  can  genuinely  change  the  face  of  things. 
Moreover,  not  even  the  wisest  of  men  can  be  trusted  with 
that  supreme  authority  which  comes  from  the  union  of 
knowledge,  capacity,  and  opportunity  with  the  power  of 
untrammelled  and  ultimate  decision.  Democracy  is  an  ex- 
pedient— perhaps  the  only  practicable  expedient — for  pre- 
venting the  concentration  in  any  single  individual  or  in  any 
single  class  of  what  inevitably  becomes,  when  so  concentrated, 
a  terrible  engine  of  oppression.  The  autocratic  emperor, 
served  by  a  trained  bureaucracy,  seems  to  the  Anglo-Saxon 
a  perilously  near  approach  to  such  a  concentration.  If 
democracy  meant,  as  early  observers  imagined,  a  similar 
concentration  of  Knowledge  and  Power  in  the  hands  of  the 
numerical  majority  for  the  time  being,  it  might  easily  become 
as  injurious  a  tyranny  as  any  autocracy.  An  actual  study 
of  the  spontaneous  democracies  of  Anglo-Saxon  workmen, 
or,  as  we  suggest,  of  any  other  democratic  institutions,  reveals 
the  splitting  up  of  this  dangerous  authority  into  two  parts. 
Whether  in  political  or  in  industrial  democracy,  though  it  is 
the  Citizen  who,  as  Elector  or  Consumer,  ultimately  gives 
the  order,  it  is  the  Professional  Expert  who  advises  what  the 
order  shall  be.1 

1  It  is  here  that  we  discover  the  answer  to  Carlyle's  question,  "How,  in 
conjunction. with  inevitable  Democracy,  indispensable  Sovereignty  is  to  exist  : 
certainly  it  is  the  hugest  question  ever  heretofore  propounded  to  Mankind " 
(Past  and  Present,  Book  IV.  chap.  i.  p.  311  of  1843  edition).  The  student  of 
Austin  will  probably  find,  in  the  industrial  democracy  of  the  future,  that 
Sovereignty,  in  the  old  sense,  is  as  hard  to  discover  as  it  already  is  in  the 
political  democracies  of  to-day  (see  Professor  D.  G.  Ritchie,  Darwin  and 
ffegel,  London,  1893).  Whatever  sphere  may  be  allotted  to  private  ownership 
of  land  and  capital,  this  will  no  more  carry  with  it  uncontrolled  power  to  fix  the 
conditions  of  industry,  than  kingship  does  of  fixing  the  conditions  of  citizenship. 
In  modern  conceptions  of  society  the  old  simple  division  into  Sovereign  and 
Subject  is  entirely  superseded  by  a  complex  differentiation  of  social  structure  and 
function. 

More  interesting,  perhaps,  in  the  present  connection,  is  Auguste  Comte's 
famous  proposal  to  separate  Social  Knowledge  from  Social  Power — to  differentiate 


846  Trade  Union  Theory 

It  is  another  aspect  of  this  paradox  that,  in  the 
democratic  state,  no  man  minds  his  own  business.  In  the 
economic  sphere  this  is  a  necessary  consequence  of  division 
of  labor ;  Robinson  Crusoe  producing  solely  for  his  own 
consumption,  being  the  last  man  who  minded  nothing  but 
his  own  business.  The  extreme  complication  brought  about 
by  universal  production  for  exchange  in  itself  implies  that 
every  one  works  with  a  view  to  fulfilling  the  desires  of  other 
people.  The  crowding  together  of  dense  populations,  and 
especially  the  co-operative  enterprises  which  then  arise,  extend 
in  every  direction  this  spontaneous  delegation  to  professional 
experts  of  what  the  isolated  individual  once  deemed  "  his 
own  business."  Thus,  the  citizen  in  a  modern  municipality  no 
longer  produces  his  own  food  or  makes  his  own  clothes  ;  no 
longer  protects  his  own  life  or  property  ;  no  longer  fetches  his 
own  water;  no  longer  makes  his  own  thoroughfares,  or  cleans  or 
lights  them  when  made  ;  no  longer  removes  his  own  refuse  or 
even  disinfects  his  own  dwelling.  He  no  longer  educates  his 
own  children,  or  doctors  and  nurses  his  own  invalids.  Trade 
Unionism  adds  to  the  long  list  of  functions  thus  delegated 
to  professional  experts  the  settlement  of  the  conditions  on 
which  the  citizen  will  agree  to  co-operate  in  the  national 
service.  In  the  fully-developed  democratic  state,  the  Citizen 
will  be  always  minding  other  people's  business.  In  his 
professional  occupation  he  will,  whether  as  brain-worker 
or  manual  laborer,  be  continually  striving  to  fulfil  the  desires 
of  those  whom  he  serves,  whilst,  as  an  Elector,  in  his  parish 

a  class  of  highly-educated  Priests,  possessing  no  authority,  from  the  Admini- 
strators, wielding  uncontrolled  authority  under  the  constant  moral  influence  of  this 
Spiritual  Power.  This  proposal,  though  embodied  in  a  fantastic  form,  seems  at 
first  sight  to  approximate  to  that  separation  between  Expert  Knowledge  and 
Ultimate  Control  which  we  regard  as  a  necessary  condition  of  Liberty.  In  reality, 
however,  it  would  secure  no  such  separation.  The  Administrators,  highly 
educated,  specialised,  and  constantly  acting  on  affairs,  would  possess  both 
Knowledge  and  Power,  and  would  be  irresistible.  Comte's  proposed  differentia- 
tion is  much  more  that  between  two  separate  classes  of  Experts — the  men  of 
pure  science,  investigating  and  discovering,  and  the  practical  men  of  action, 
applying  to  the  affairs  of  daily  life  the  generalisations  of  science.  In  democracy, 
these  two  classes  of  Experts,  both  absolutely  essential  to  progress,  are  neither  of 
them  entrusted  with  ultimate  decision. 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  847 

or  his  co-operative  society,  his  Trade  Union  or  his  political 
association,  he  will  be  perpetually  passing  judgment  on  issues 
in  which  his  personal  interest  is  no  greater  than  that  of  his 
fellows. 

If,  then,  we  are  asked  whether  democracy,  as  shown  by 
an  analysis  of  Trade  Unionism,  is  consistent  with  Individual 
Liberty,  we  are  compelled  to  answer  by  asking,  What  is 
Liberty  ?  If  Liberty  means  every  man  being  his  own 
master,  and  following  his  own  impulses,  then  it  is  clearly 
inconsistent,  not  so  much  with  democracy  or  any  other 
particular  form  of  government,  as  with  the  crowding  together 
of  population  in  dense  masses,  division  of  labor,  and,  as  we 
think,  civilisation  itself.  What  particular  individuals,  sec- 
tions, or  classes  usually  mean  by  "freedom  of  contract," 
"  freedom  of  association,"  or  "  freedom  of  enterprise  "  is  free- 
dom of  opportunity  to  use  the  power  that  they  happen  to 
possess  ;  that  is  to  say,  to  compel  other  less  powerful  people 
to  accept  their  terms.  This  sort  of  personal  freedom  in  a 
community  composed  of  unequal  units  is  not  distinguishable 
from  compulsion.  It  is,  therefore,  necessary  to  define  Liberty 
before  talking  about  it,  a  definition  which  every  man  will 
frame  according  to  his  own  view  of  what  is  socially  desirable. 
We  ourselves  understand  by  the  words  "  Liberty  "  or  "  Free- 
dom," not  any  quantum  of  natural  or  inalienable  rights,  but 
such  conditions  of  existence  in  the  community  as  do,  in 
practice,  result  in  the  utmost  possible  development  of  faculty 
in  the  individual  human  being.1  Now,  in  this  sense  demo- 
cracy is  not  only  consistent  with  Liberty,  but  is,  as  it  seems 
to  us,  the  only  way  of  securing  the  largest  amount  of  it.  It 
is  open  to  argument  whether  other  forms  of  government  may 
not  achieve  a  fuller  development  of  the  faculties  of  particular 
individuals  or  classes.  To  an  autocrat,  untrammelled  rule  over 
a  whole  kingdom  may  mean  an  exercise  of  his  individual 
faculties,  and  a  development  of  his  individual  personality,  such 
as  no  other  situation  in  life  would  afford.  An  aristocracy,  or 

1  "Liberty,  in  fact,  means  just  so  far  as  it  is  realised,  the  right  man  in  the 
right  place." — Sir  John  Seeley,  Lectures  and  Essay 's,  p.  109. 


848  Trade  Union  Theory 

government  by  one  class  in  the  interests  ot  one  class,  may 
conceivably  enable  that  class  to  develop  a  perfection  in 
physical  grace  or  intellectual  charm  attainable  by  no  other 
system  of  society.  Similarly,  it  might  be  argued  that,  where 
the  ownership  of  the  means  of  production  and  the  admini- 
stration of  industry  are  unreservedly  left  to  the  capitalist 
class,  this  "  freedom  of  enterprise  "  would  result  in  a  develop- 
ment of  faculty  among  the  captains  of  industry  which  could 
not  otherwise  be  reached.  We  dissent  from  all  these  pro- 
positions, if  only  on  the  ground  that  the  fullest  development 
of  personal  character  requires  the  pressure  of  discipline 
as  well  as  the  stimulus  of  opportunity.  But,  however  un- 
trammelled power  may  affect  the  character  of  those  who  pos- 
sess it,  autocracy,  aristocracy,  and  plutocracy  have  all,  from 
the  point  of  view  of  the  lover  of  liberty,  one  fatal  defect. 
They  necessarily  involve  a  restriction  in  the  opportunity  for 
development  of  faculty  among  the  great  mass  of  the  population. 
It  is  only  when  the  resources  of  the  nation  are  deliberately 
organised  and  dealt  with  for  the  benefit,  not  of  particular  indi- 
viduals or  classes,  but  of  the  entire  community  ;  when  the 
administration  of  industry,  as  of  every  other  branch  of 
human  affairs,  becomes  the  function  of  specialised  experts, 
working  through  deliberately  adjusted  Common  Rules  ;  and 
when  the  ultimate  decision  on  policy  rests  in  no  other  hands 
than  those  of  the  citizens  themselves,  that  the  maximum 
aggregate  development  of  individual  intellect  and  individual 
character  in  the  community  as  a  whole  can  be  attained. 

For  our  analysis  helps  us  to  disentangle,  from  the 
complex  influences  on  individual  development,  those 
caused  by  democracy  itself.  The  universal  specialisation 
and  delegation  which,  as  we  suggest,  democratic  insti- 
tutions involve,  necessarily  imply  a  great  increase  in 
capacity  and  efficiency,  if  only  because  specialisation  in 
service  means  expertness,  and  delegation  compels  selection. 
This  deepening  and  narrowing  of  professional  skill  may  be 
expected,  in  the  fully  -  developed  democratic  state,  to  be 
accompanied  by  a  growth  in  culture  of  which  our  present 


Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy  849 

imperfect  organisation  gives  us  no  adequate  idea.  So  long 
as  life  is  one  long  scramble  for  personal  gain — still  more, 
when  it  is  one  long  struggle  against  destitution — there  is  no 
free  time  or  strength  for  much  development  of  the  sympa- 
thetic, intellectual,  artistic,  or  religious  faculties.  When  the 
conditions  of  employment  are  deliberately  regulated  so  as  to 
secure  adequate  food,  education,  and  leisure  to  every  capable 
citizen,  the  great  mass  of  the  population  will,  for  the  first 
time,  have  any  real  chance  of  expanding  in  friendship  and 
family  affection,  and  of  satisfying  the  instinct  for  knowledge 
or  beauty.  It  is  an  even  more  unique  attribute  of  demo- 
cracy that  it  is  always  taking  the  mind  of  the  individual 
off  his  own  narrow  interests  and  immediate  concerns,  and 
forcing  him  to  give  his  thought  and  leisure,  not  to  satisfying 
his  own  desires,  but  to  considering  the  needs  and  desires  of 
his  fellows.  As  an  Elector — still  more  as  a  chosen  Repre- 
sentative1— in  his  parish,  in  his  professional  association,  in  his 
co-operative  society,  or  in  the  wider  political  institutions  of 
his  state,  the  "  average  sensual  man  "  is  perpetually  impelled 
to  appreciate  and  to  decide  issues  of  public  policy.  The 
working  of  democratic  institutions  means,  therefore,  one 
long  training  in  enlightened  altruism,  one  continual  weigh- 
ing, not  of  the  advantage  of  the  particular  act  to  the 
particular  individual  at  the  particular  moment,  but  of  those 
"  larger  expediencies  "  on  which  all  successful  conduct  of  social 
life  depends. 

If  now,  at  the  end  of  this  long  analysis,  we  try  to  formu- 
late our  dominant  impression,  it  is  a  sense  of  the  vastness  and 
complexity  of  democracy  itself.  Modern  civilised  states  are 
driven  to  this  complication  by  the  dense  massing  of  their  popu- 
lations, and  the  course  of  industrial  development.  The  very 
desire  to  secure  mobility  in  the  crowd  compels  the  adoption  of 
one  regulation  after  another,  which  limit  the  right  of  every  man 
to  use  the  air,  the  water,  the  land,  and  even  the  artificially 
produced  instruments  of  production,  in  the  way  that  he  may 
think  best.  The  very  discovery  of  improved  industrial 
methods,  by  leading  to  specialisation,  makes  manual  laborer 
VOL.  II  31 


850  Trade  Union  Theory 

and  brain-worker  alike  dependent  on  the  rest  of  the  com- 
munity for  the  means  of  subsistence,  and  subordinates  them, 
even  in  their  own  crafts,  to  the  action  of  others.  In  the 
world  of  civilisation  and  progress,  no  man  can  be  his  own 
master.  But  the  very  fact  that,  in  modern  society,  the 
individual  thus  necessarily  loses  control  over  his  own  life, 
makes  him  desire  to  regain  collectively  what  has  become 
individually  impossible.  Hence  the  irresistible  tendency  to 
popular  government,  in  spite  of  all  its  difficulties  and  dangers. 
But  democracy  is  still  the  Great  Unknown.  Of  its  full  scope 
and  import  we  can  yet  catch  only  glimpses.  As  one  depart- 
ment of  social  life  after  another  becomes  the  subject  of  careful 
examination,  we  shall  gradually  attain  to  a  more  complete 
vision.  Our  own  tentative  conclusions,  derived  from  the  study 
of  one  manifestation  of  the  democratic  spirit,  may,  we  hope, 
not  only  suggest  hypotheses  for  future  verification,  but  also 
stimulate  other  students  to  carry  out  original  investigations 
into  the  larger  and  perhaps  more  significant  types  of  demo- 
cratic organisation. 


APPENDICES 


APPENDIX    II1 

THE    BEARING    OF    INDUSTRIAL    PARASITISM    AND    THE  POLICY   OF   A 
NATIONAL    MINIMUM    ON    THE    FREE    TRADE    CONTROVERSY 

THE  existence  of  parasitic  trades  supplies  the  critic  of  inter- 
national Free  Trade  with  an  argument  which  has  not  yet  been 
adequately  met.  To  the  enlightened  patriot,  ambitious  for  the 
utmost  possible  development  of  his  country,  it  has  always  seemed  a 
drawback  to  Free  Trade,  that  it  tended,  to  a  greater  or  lesser  extent, 
to  limit  his  fellow-countrymen's  choice  of  occupation.  Thus,  one 
community,  possessing  great  mineral  wealth,  might  presently  find 
a  large  proportion  of  its  population  driven  underground  ;  another 
might  see  itself  doomed  to  become  the  mere  stock- yard  and 
slaughter-house  of  the  world ;  whilst  the  destiny  of  a  third  might  be 
to  have  its  countryside  depopulated,  and  the  bulk  of  its  citizens 
engaged  in  the  manufacture,  in  the  slum  tenements  of  great  cities, 
of  cheap  boots  and  ready-made  clothing  for  the  whole  habitable 
globe.  To  this  contention  the  answer  has  usually  been  that  the 
specialisation  of  national  function,  whilst  never  likely  to  be  carried 
to  an  extreme,  was  economically  advantageous  all  round.  Such  a 
reply  ignores  the  possibility  of  industrial  parasitism.  If  unfettered 
freedom  of  trade  ensured  that  each  nation  would  retain  the  industry 
in  which  its  efficiency  was  highest,  and  its  potentialities  were 
greatest,  this  international  "  division  of  labor "  might  be  accepted 
as  the  price  to  be  paid  for  getting  every  commodity  with  the  mini- 
mum of  labor.  But  under  unfettered  freedom  of  competition  there 
is,  as  we  have  seen,  no  such  guarantee.  Within  a  trade,  one  district 
may  drive  all  the  rest  out  of  the  business,  not  by  reason  of  any 
genuine  advantage  in  productive  efficiency,  but  merely  because  the 
workers  in  the  successful  district  get  some  aid  from  the  rates  or 
from  other  sources.  Within  a  community,  too,  unless  care  be 

1  See    Part    III.    chap,    ui.    "The    Economic    Characteristics    of    Trade 
Unionism." 


864  Appendix  II 

taken  to  prevent  any  kind  of  parasitism,  one  trade  or  one  process 
may  flourish  and  expand  at  the  expense  of  all  the  rest,  not  because 
it  is  favored  by  natural  advantages  or  acquired  capacity,  but  merely 
by  reason  of  some  sort  of  "  bounty."  Under  Free  Trade  the  inter- 
national pressure  for  cheapness  is  always  tending  to  select,  as  the 
speciality  of  each  nation  in  the  world-market,  those  of  its  industries 
in  which  the  employers  can  produce  most  cheaply.  If  each  trade 
were  self-supporting,  the  increased  efficiency  of  the  regulated  trades 
would  bring  these  easily  to  the  top,  notwithstanding  (or  rather,  in 
consequence  of)  the  relatively  high  wages,  short  hours,  and  good 
sanitary  conditions  enjoyed  by  their  operatives.  If,  however,  the 
employers  in  some  trades  can  obtain  labor  partially  subsisted  from 
other  sources,  or  if  they  are  free  to  use  up  in  their  service  not  only 
the  daily  renewed  energy,  but  also  the  capital  value  of  successive 
relays  of  deteriorating  workers,  they  may  well  be  able  to  export  more 
cheaply  than  the  self-supporting  trades,  to  the  detriment  of  these, 
and  of  the  community  itself.  And  this,  as  we  have  seen,  is  the 
direct  result  of  the  very  freedom  of  Individual  Bargaining  on  which 
the  Free  Traders  rely.  Indeed,  if  we  follow  out  to  its  logical  con- 
clusion the  panacea  of  unlimited  freedom  of  competitive  industry 
both  within  the  country  and  without,  we  arrive  at  a  state  of  things 
in  which,  out  of  all  the  various  trades  that  each  community  pursues, 
those  might  be  "  selected  "  for  indefinite  expansion,  and  for  the 
supply  of  the  world-market,  in  which  the  employers  enjoyed  the 
advantage  of  the  greatest  bounty;  those,  for  instance,  which  were 
carried  on  by  operatives  assisted  from  other  classes,  or,  still  worse, 
those  supplied  with  successive  relays  of  necessitous  wage-earners 
standing  at  such  a  disadvantage  in  the  sale  of  their  labor  that  they 
obtained  in  return  wages  so  low  and  conditions  so  bad  as  to  be 
positively  insufficient  to  maintain  them  permanently  in  health  and 
efficiency.  Instead  of  a  world  in  which  each  community  devoted 
itself  to  what  it  could  do  best,  we  should  get,  with  the  "  sweated 
trades,"  a  world  in  which  each  community  did  that  which  reduced 
its  people  to  the  lowest  degradation.  Hence  the  Protectionist  is  right 
when  he  asserts  that,  assuming  unfettered  individual  competition 
within  each  community,  international  free  trade  may  easily  tend,  not 
to  a  good,  but  to  an  exceedingly  vicious  international  division  of 
labor. 

This  criticism  is  not  dealt  with,  so  far  as  we  are  aware,  in  any  of 
the  publications  of  the  Cobden  Club,  nor  by  the  economic  defenders 
of  the  Free  Trade  position.  Thus,  Professor  Bastable,  in  his  lucid 
exposition  of  The  Theory  of  International  Trade  (2nd  edition, 
London,  1897),  assumes  throughout  that  the  prices  of  commodities 


The  Free  Trade  Controversy  865 

in  the  home  market,  and  thus  their  relative  export,  will  vary  accord- 
ing to  the  actual  "  cost  of  production,"  instead  of  merely  according 
to  their  "expenses  of  production,"  to  the  capitalist  entrepreneur. 
Yet  it  is  evidently  not  the  sum  of  human  efforts  and  sacrifices 
involved  in  the  production  that  affects  the  import  or  export  trade, 
but  simply  the  expenses  that  production  involves  to  the  capitalist. 
This  absence  of  any  reference  to  the  possibility  of  the  cheapness 
being  due  to  underpaid  (because  subsidised  or  deteriorating)  labor, 
enables  Professor  Bastable  optimistically  to  infer  (p.  18)  that  "the 
rule  is  that  each  nation  exports  those  commodities  for  the  pro- 
duction of  which  it  is  specially  suited."  Similarly  Lord  Farrer,  in 
The  State  in  its  Relation  to  Trade  (London,  1883),  when  stating 
the  argument  against  Protection,  simply  assumes  (p.  134)  that  the 
industry  for  which  the  country  is  specially  suited  pays  higher  wages 
than  others.  "One  thing  is  certain,  viz.  that  we  cannot  buy  the 
French  or  Swiss  ribbons  without  making  and  selling  something  which 
we  can  make  better  and  cheaper  than  ribbons,  and  which  consequently 
brings  more  profit  to  our  manufacturer,  and  better  wages  to  our 
workmen?  And  Mr.  B.  R.  Wise,  seeking  in  his  Industrial  Freedom 
to  revise  and  restate  the  Free  Trade  argument  in  the  light  of 
practical  experience,  is  driven  to  warn  his  readers  that  "  it  cannot  be 
too  often  repeated  that  the  competition  of  abstract  political  economy 
— that  competition  through  which  alone  political  economy  has  any 
pretension  to  the  character  of  a  science — is  a  competition  between 
equal  units,"  .  .  .  and  nothing  could  be  further  from  the  truth  than 
to  suppose  that  "  free  competition "  in  the  labor  market  bore  any 
resemblance  to  the  competition  between  equal  units  that  the  current 
expositions  of  Free  Trade  theory  required.1 

But  though  the  existence  of  parasitic  trades  knocks  the  bottom 
out  of  the  argument  for  laisser  faire,  it  adds  no  weight  to  the  case 
for  a  protective  tariff.  What  the  protectionist  is  concerned  about 
is  the  contraction  of  some  of  his  country's  industries ;  the  evil 
revealed  by  our  analysis  is  the  expansion  of  certain  others.  The 
advocate  of  a  protective  tariff  aims  at  excluding  imports ;  the 
opponent  of  "sweating,"  on  the  other  hand,  sees  with  regret  the 
rapid  growth  of  particular  exports,  which  imply  the  extension  within 
the  country  of  its  most  highly  subsidised  or  most  parasitic  industries. 
Hence,  whatever  ingenious  arguments  may  be  found  in  favor  of 
a  protective  tariff,2  such  a  remedy  fails  altogether  to  cope  with  this 

1  B.  R.  Wise,  Industrial  Freedom  (London,  1882),  pp.  13,  15. 

2  For  any  adequate  presentment  of  the  case  against  international  free  trade, 
the  student  must  turn  to  Germany  or  the  United  States,  notably  to  Friedrich  List, 
The  National  System  of  Political  Economy,  published  in  Germany  in   1841,  and 

VOL.  II  3  K 


866  Appendix  II 

particular  evil.  If  the  expansion  of  the  industries  which  England 
pursues  to  the  greatest  economic  advantage — say,  for  instance,  coal 
mining  and  shipbuilding,  textile  manufacture  and  machine-making 
— is  being  checked,  this  is  not  because  coal  and  ships,  textiles  and 
machinery  are  being  imported  into  England  from  abroad,  but  because 
other  less  advantageous  industries  within  England  itself,  by  reason  of 
being  favored  with  some  kind  of  bounty,  have  secured  the  use  of 
some  of  the  nation's  brains  and  capital,  and  some  of  its  export 
trade.  This  diversion  would  clearly  not  be  counteracted  by  putting 
an  import  duty  on  the  small  and  exceptional  amounts  of  coal  and 
shipping,  textiles  and  machinery  that  we  actually  import,  for  this 
would  leave  unchecked  the  expansion  of  the  subsidised  trades, 
which,  if  the  subsidy  were  only  large  enough,  might  go  on  absorbing 
more  and  more  of  the  nation's  brains  and  capital,  and  more  and 
more  of  its  export  trade.  To  put  it  concretely,  England  might 
find  its  manufactures  and  its  exports  composed,  in  increasing 
proportions,  of  slop  clothing,  cheap  furniture  and  knives,  and  the 
whole  range  of  products  of  the  sweated  trades,  to  the  detriment  of 
its  present  staple  industries  of  cotton  and  coal,  ships  and  machinery, 
In  the  same  way,  every  other  country  might  find  its  own  manufac- 
tures and  its  own  exports  increasingly  made  up  of  the  products  of 
its  own  parasitic  trades.  In  short,  the  absolute  exclusion  by  each 
country  of  the  imports  competing  with  its  own  products  would 
not,  any  more  than  Free  Trade  itself,  prevent  the  expansion  within  the 
country  of  those  industries  which  afforded  to  its  wage-earners  the 
worst  conditions  of  employment.1 

A  dim  inkling  of  this  result  of  international  competition  is  at  the 
back  of  recent  proposals  for  the  international  application  of  the 
Device  of  the  Common  Rule.  During  the  past  seven  years  states- 
men have  begun  to  feel  their  way  towards  an  international  uniformity 
of  factory  legislation,  so  as  to  make  all  cotton  mills,  for  instance, 
work  identical  hours,  and  workmen  are  aspiring  to  an  international 

translated  by  Sampson  Lloyd  (London,  1885)  and  the  works  of  H.  C.  Carey. 
The  arguments  of  List  and  Carey  were  popularised  in  America  by  such  writers  as 
Professor  R.  E.  Thompson,  Political  Economy  with  Especial  Reference  to  the  In-*, 
dustrial  History  of  Nations  (Philadelphia,  1882),  H.  M.  Hoyt,  Protection  and 
Free  Trade  the  Scientific  Validity  and  Economic  Operation  of  Defensive  Dtitics 
in  the  United  States,  3rd  edition  (New  York,  1886);  whilst  another  line  has 
been  taken  by  Francis  Bowen,  American  Political  Economy.  The  whole 
position  has  been  restated  by  Professor  Patten,  in  The  Economic  Basis  of 
Protection  (Philadelphia,  1890),  and  other  suggestive  works  which  deserve  more 
attention  in  England. 

1  It  is  unnecessary  to  notice  the  despairing  suggestion  that  a  protective  duty 
should  be  placed  on  the  products  of  the  sweated  trades  themselves.  But  these, 


The  Free  Trade  Controversy  867 

Trade  Unionism,  by  means  of  which,  for  example,  the  coalminers, 
cotton-operatives,  glass-workers,  or  dock-laborers  of  the  world  might 
simultaneously  move  for  better  conditions.  If,  indeed,  we  could 
arrive  at  an  International  Minimum  of  education  and  sanitation, 
leisure  and  wages,  below  which  no  country  would  permit  any  section 
of  its  manual  workers  to  be  employed  in  any  trade  whatsoever, 
industrial  parasitism  would  be  a  thing  of  the  past.  But  inter- 
nationalism of  this  sort — a  "zollverein  based  on  a  universal 
Factory  Act  and  Fair  Wages  clause  " — is  obviously  Utopian.  What 
is  not  so  generally  understood,  either  by  statesmen  or  by  Trade 
Unionists,  is  that  international  uniformity  of  conditions  within  a 
particular  trade,  which  is  all  that  is  ever  contemplated,  would  do 
little  or  nothing  to  remedy  the  evil  of  industrial  parasitism.  In 
this  matter,  as  in  others,  a  man's  worst  foes  are  those  of  his  own 
household.  Let  us  imagine,  for  instance,  that,  by  an  international 
factory  act,  all  the  cotton  mills  in  the  world  were  placed  upon  a 
uniform  basis  of  hours  and  child-labor,  sanitation  and  precautions 
against  accidents.  Let  us  carry  the  uniformity  even  a  stage 
further,  and  imagine  what  is  impossible,  an  international  uniformity 
of  wage  in  all  cotton  mills.  All  this  would  in  no  way  prevent  a 
diversion  of  the  nation's  brains  and  capital  away  from  cotton  manu- 
facture to  some  other  industry,  in  which,  by  reason  of  a  subsidy  or 
bounty,  the  employer  stood  at  a  greater  relative  advantage  towards 
the  home  or  foreign  consumer.  The  country  having  the  greatest 
natural  advantages  and  technical  capacity  for  cotton  manufacture 
would  doubtless  satisfy  the  great  bulk  of  the  world's  demand  for 
cotton  goods.  But,  if  there  existed  within  that  same  country  any 
trades  carried  on  by  parasitic  labor,  or  assisted  by  any  kind  of 
bounty,  it  would  obtain  less  of  the  cotton  trade  of  the  world  than 
would  otherwise  be  the  case ;  the  marginal  business  in  cotton  would 
tend  to  be  abandoned  to  the  next  most  efficient  country,  in  order  that 
some  brains  and  capital  might,  to  the  economic  loss  of  the  nation  and 
of  the  world,  take  advantage  of  the  subsidy  or  bounty.1  We  see, 

as  we  have  seen  (if  they  are  really  parasitic  industries  like  the  wholesale 
clothing  manufacture,  and  not  merely  self-supporting  but  unprogressive  industries 
like  English  agriculture),  will  usually  be  exporting  trades,  not  subject  to  the 
competition  of  foreign  imports.  Merely  to  put  an  import  duty  on  the  odds  and 
ends  of  foreign-made  clothing  or  cheap  knives  that  England  imports  would  in 
no  way  strengthen  the  strategic  position,  as  against  the  employer,  of  the 
sweated  outworkers  of  East  London  or  Sheffield,  or  render  the  respectable  young 
women  of  Leeds  less  eager  to  be  taken  on  at  a  pocket-money  wage  in  the 
well-appointed  clothing  factories  of  that  city. 

1  This  hypothetical  case  is,  we  believe,  not  unlike  the  actual  condition  of  the 
cotton  manufacture  in  the  United  Kingdom  at  the  present  time,  in  spite  of  the 
absence  of  international  uniformity. 


868  Appendix  II 

therefore,  that  even  an  international  uniformity  of  conditions 
within  a  particular  trade  would  not,  in  face  of  industrial  parasitism 
at  home,  prevent  the  most  advantageously  situated  country  from 
losing  a  portion  of  this  uniformly  regulated  trade.  The  parasitic 
trades  have,  in  fact,  upon  the  international  distribution  of  industry, 
an  effect  strictly  analogous  to  that  which  they  have  upon  the  home 
trade.  By  ceding  as  a  bribe  to  the  consumer  the  bounty  or  subsidy 
which  they  receive,  they  cause  the  capital,  brains,  and  labor  of  the 
world  to  be  distributed,  in  the  aggregate,  in  a  less  productive  way 
than  would  otherwise  have  been  the  case. 

We  can  now  see  that  the  economists  of  the  middle  of  the  century 
only  taught,  and  the  Free  Trade  statesmen  only  learnt,  one-half  of 
their  lesson.  They  were  so  much  taken  up  with  the  idea  of  remov- 
ing the  fiscal  barriers  between  nations  that  they  failed  to  follow  up 
the  other  part  of  their  own  conception,  the  desirability  of  getting  rid 
of  bounties  of  every  kind.  M'Culloch  and  Nassau  Senior,  Cobden 
and  Bright,  realised  clearly  enough  that  the  grant  of  money  aid  to  a 
particular  industry  out  of  the  rates  or  taxes  enabled  that  industry  to 
secure  more  of  the  nation's  brains  and  capital,  and  more  of  the 
world's  trade,  than  was  economically  advantageous.  They  even 
understood  that  the  use  of  unpaid  slave  labor  constituted  just  such 
a  bounty  as  a  rate  in  aid  of  wages.  But  they  never  clearly  recog- 
nised that  the  employment  of  children,  the  overwork  of  women,  or 
the  payment  of  wages  insufficient  for  the  maintenance  of  the  opera- 
tive in  full  industrial  efficiency  stood,  economically,  on  the  same 
footing.  If  the  object  of  "  Free  Trade  "  is  to  promote  such  a  dis- 
tribution of  capital,  brains,  and  labor  among  countries  and  among 
industries,  as  will  result  in  the  greatest  possible  production,  with  the 
least  expenditure  of  human  efforts  and  sacrifices,  the  factory  legisla- 
tion of  Robert  Owen  and  Lord  Shaftesbury  formed  as  indispensable 
a  part  of  the  Free  Trade  movement  as  the  tariff  reforms  of  Cobden 
and  Bright.  "During  that  period,"  wrote  the  Duke  of  Argyll  of 
the  nineteenth  century,1  "two  great  discoveries  have  been  made 
in  the  Science  of  Government :  the  one  is  the  immense  advantage 
of  abolishing  restrictions  upon  Trade;  the  other  is  the  absolute 
necessity  of  imposing  restrictions  on  labor.  .  .  .  And  so  the 
Factory  Acts,  instead  of  being  excused  as  exceptional,  and  pleaded 
for  as  justified  only  under  extraordinary  conditions,  ought  to  be 
recognised  as  in  truth  the  first  legislative  recognition  of  a  great 
Natural  Law,  quite  as  important  as  Freedom  of  Trade,  and  which, 
like  this  last,  was  yet  destined  to  claim  for  itself  wider  and  wider 
application." 

1  The  Reign  of  Law  (London,  1867),  pp.  367,  399. 


The  Free  Trade  Controversy  869 

Seen  in  this  light,  the  proposal  for  the  systematic  enforcement, 
throughout  each  country,  of  its  own  National  Minimum  of  educa- 
tion, sanitation,  leisure,  and  wages,  becomes  a  necessary  completion 
of  the  Free  Trade  policy.  Only  by  enforcing  such  a  minimum  on 
all  its  industries  can  a  nation  prevent  the  evil  expansion  of  its 
parasitic  trades  being  enormously  aggravated  by  its  international 
trade.  And  there  is  no  advantage  in  this  National  Minimum  being 
identical  or  uniform  throughout  the  world.  Paradoxical  as  it  may 
seem  to  the  practical  man,  a  country  enforcing  a  relatively  high 
National  Minimum  would  not  lose  its  export  trade  to  other  countries 
having  lower  conditions,  any  more,  indeed,  than  a  country  in  which 
a  high  Standard  of  Life  spontaneously  exists,  loses  its  trade  to  others 
in  which  the  standard  is  lower.  If  the  relatively  high  National 
Minimum  caused  a  proportionate  increase  in  the  productive  efficiency 
of  the  community,  it  would  obviously  positively  strengthen  its  com- 
mand of  the  world  market.  But  even  if  the  level  of  the  National 
Minimum  were,  by  democratic  pressure,  forced  up  farther  or  more 
rapidly  than  was  compensated  for  by  an  equivalent  increase  in 
national  efficiency,  so  that  the  expenses  of  production  to  the 
capitalist  employer  became  actually  higher  than  those  in  other 
countries,  this  would  not  stop  (or  even  restrict  the  total  of)  our 
exports.  "  General  low  wages,"  emphatically  declare  the  econo- 
mists, "  never  caused  any  country  to  undersell  its  rivals,  nor  did 
general  high  wages  ever  hinder  it  from  doing  so." x  So  long 
as  we  continued  to  desire  foreign  products,  and  therefore  to  import 
them  in  undiminished  quantity,  enough  exports  would  continue  to 
be  sent  abroad  to  discharge  our  international  indebtedness.  We 
should,  it  is  true,  not  get  our  tea  and  foodstuffs,  or  whatever  else  we 
imported,  so  cheaply  as  we  now  do ;  the  consumer  of  foreign  goods 
would  find,  indeed,  that  these  had  risen  in  price,  just  as  English 
goods  had.  If  we  ignore  the  intervention  of  currency,  and  imagine 
foreign  trade  to  be  actually  conducted,  as  it  is  virtually,  by  a  system 
of  barter,  we  shall  understand  both  this  rise  of  price  of  foreign  goods, 
and  the  continued  export  of  English  goods,  even  when  they  are  all 
dearer  than  the  corresponding  foreign  products.  For  the  English 
importing  firms,  having  somehow  to  discharge  their  international 
indebtedness,  and  finding  no  English  products  which  they  can 
export  at  a  profit,  will  be  driven  to  export  some  even  at  a  loss — a 
loss  which,  like  the  item  of  freight  or  any  other  expense  of  carrying 
on  their  business,  they  will  add  to  the  price  charged  to  the  con- 
sumer of  foreign  imports.  They  will,  of  course,  select  for  export 

1  J.   S.  Mill,  Principles  of  Political  Economy,   Book  III.   chap.   xxv.   §  4, 
p.  414  of  1865  edition. 


8  70  Appendix  II 

those  English  products  on  which  the  loss  is  least — that  is  to  suy, 
those  in  which  England  stands  at  relatively  the  greatest  advantage, 
or,  what  comes  to  the  same  thing,  the  least  disadvantage.  There- 
fore, if  the  rise  in  the  expense  of  English  production  were  uniform, 
not  only  the  total,  but  also  the  distribution  of  our  exports  would 
remain  unaffected.  The  foreign  consumer,  by  reason  of  the  cheap- 
ness of  production  of  his  own  goods,  will  then  be  getting  English- 
made  goods  at  a  lower  price  than  would  otherwise  be  the  case — it 
may  be,  even  a  lower  price  than  the  Englishman  is  buying  them 
at  in  his  own  country — just  as  the  Englishman  at  the  present  time 
buys  American  products  in  London  at  the  comparatively  low  level 
of  English  prices,  and  sometimes  actually  cheaper  than  they  are  sold 
at  in  New  York.  For  this  process  of  exporting  at  an  apparent  loss, 
as  a  set -off  against  a  profitable  import  trade,  actually  takes  place, 
now  in  one  country,  now  in  another.1  It  sometimes  happens  that 
the  same  firm  of  merchants  both  exports  and  imports  :  more  usually, 
however,  the  compensatory  process  is  performed  through  the  banking 
houses,  and  manifests  itself  in  those  fluctuations  of  the  foreign 
exchanges,  which,  though  clear  enough  to  the  eye  of  the  practical 
financier  and  the  economist,  shroud  all  the  processes  of  interna- 
tional exchange  from  the  ordinary  man  by  a  dense  veil  of  paradox. 

The  practical  check  to  a  rise  in  the  National  Minimum  comes, 
indeed,  not  from  the  side  of  international  trade,  but,  as  we  have 
already  explained,  from  the  home  taxpayer  and  the  home  consumer. 
Every  rise  in  the  National  Minimum  not  compensated  for  by 
some  corresponding  increase  in  the  efficiency  with  which  the 
national  industry  was  carried  on  would  imply  an  increase  in  the 
number  of  the  unemployable,  and  thus  in  the  Poor  Rate  or  other 
provision  for  their  maintenance ;  and  every  increase  in  the  expenses 
of  production  would  be  resented  as  a  rise  in  price  by  the  bulk  of 
the  population.  The  lowlier  grades  of  labor,  employing  a  majority 
of  the  citizens,  would  clearly  benefit  by  the  improvement  which  the 
rise  would  cause  in  their  own  conditions.  Other  grades  of  pro- 
ducers, including  the  brain-working  directors  of  industry,  would  find 
their  own  "rent"  of  specialised  or  otherwise  exceptional  faculty 
undiminished,  even  if  they  had  to  pay  away  more  of  it  in  taxes  and 
higher  prices.  The  great  and  growing  army  of  officials  on  fixed 
incomes  would  loudly  complain  of  the  increased  cost  of  living, 
which  would  presently  be  met  by  a  rise  in  salaries.  But  the  real 

1  When,  for  instance,  the  export  of  gold  is  prohibited,  or  when  all  the  gold 
has  already  been  sent  away  ;  or  when,  for  any  reason,  less  expensive  ways  of  dis- 
charging a  balance  of  indebtedness  do  not  exist. — See  Goschen's  Theory  of  the 
Foreign  Exchanges,  or  Clare's  A. B.C.  of  the  Foreign  Exchanges. 


The  Free  Trade  Controversy  871 

sufferers  would  be  the  rentier  class,  existing  unproductively  on  their 
investments.  These  persons  would  be  hit  both  ways  :  they  would 
find  themselves,  by  increased  taxation,  saddled  with  most  of  the 
cost  of  the  unemployable,  and  by  higher  prices,  charged  with  at  least 
their  share  of  the  increase  in  the  nation's  wage-bill.  Such  a  practical 
diminution  in  the  net  income  of  the  dividend-receiving  classes  would, 
from  Ricardo  down  to  Cairnes,  have  been  supposed  to  correct  itself 
by  a  falling  off  in  their  rate  of  saving,  and  therefore,  as  it  was 
supposed,  in  the  rate  of  accumulation  of  additional  capital.  This, 
as  we  have  seen,  can  no  longer  be  predicted,  even  if  we  cannot  yet 
bring  ourselves  to  believe,  with  Sir  Josiah  Child  and  Adam  Smith, 
that  the  shrinking  of  incomes  from  investments  would  actually 
quicken  production  and  stimulate  increased  accumulation.  What  it 
might  conceivably  do  would  be  to  drive  the  rentier  class  to  live 
increasingly  abroad,  with  indirect  consequences  which  have  to  be 
considered. 

We  have  hitherto  left  on  one  side  the  possible  migration  of 
capital  from  a  country,  in  which  the  National  Minimum  had  been 
unduly  raised,  to  others  in  which  labor  could  be  hired  more  cheaply. 
This  is  hindered,  to  an  extent  which  we  do  not  think  is  sufficiently 
appreciated,  by  the  superior  amenity  of  English  life  to  the  able 
business  man.  So  long  as  our  captains  of  industry  prefer  to  live  in 
England,  go  abroad  with  reluctance  even  for  high  salaries,  and  return 
to  their  own  country  as  soon  as  they  possibly  can,  it  will  pay  the 
owners  of  capital  to  employ  it  where  this  high  business  talent  is 
found.  The  danger  to  English  industrial  supremacy  would  seem  to 
us,  therefore,  to  lie  in  any  diminution  of  the  attractiveness  of  life  in 
England  to  the  able  brain-working  Englishman.  An  increase  in  the 
taxation  of  this  class,  or  a  rise  in  the  price  of  the  commodities  they 
consume,  is  not  of  great  moment,  provided  that  facilities  exist  for  them 
to  make  adequate  incomes  ;  and  these  rewards  of  exceptional  talent 
are,  it  will  be  remembered,  in  no  way  diminished  by  the  Device  of 
the  Common  Rule.  But  any  loss  of  public  consideration,  or  any 
migration  of  their  rentier  friends  or  relations,  might  conceivably 
weaken  their  tie  to  England,  and  might,  therefore,  need  to  be  counter- 
acted by  some  increase  in  their  amenities  or  rewards.1  Our  own 
opinion  is  that  this  increased  amenity,  and  also  this  increased  reward 
of  exceptional  ability,  would  actually  be  the  result  of  a  high  National 
Minimum.  It  is  difficult  for  the  Englishman  of  to-day  to  form  any 

1  It  would  be  interesting  to  inquire  how  far  the  fatal  "absenteeism"  of 
Ireland's  men  of  genius  has  been  caused  or  increased  by  the  reduction  of  Dublin 
from  the  position  of  a  wealthy  and  intellectual  capital  to  that  of  a  second-rate 
provincial  town. 


872  Appendix  II 

adequate  idea  of  how  much  pleasanter  English  life  would  be  if  we 
were,  once  for  all,  rid  of  the  slum  and  sweating  den,  and  no  class  of 
workers  found  itself  condemned  to  grinding  poverty ;  if  science  had 
so  transformed  our  unhealthy  trades  that  no  section  of  the  popula- 
tion suffered  unnecessarily  from  accident  or  disease ;  and  if  every 
grade  of  citizens  was  rapidly  rising  in  health,  intelligence,  and 
character. 

It  follows  that  each  community  is  economically  free,  without  feat 
of  losing  its  foreign  trade,  to  fix  its  own  National  Minimum,  accord- 
ing to  its  own  ideas  of  what  is  desirable,  its  own  stage  of  industrial 
development,  and  its  own  customs  of  life.  The  course  and  extent 
of  international  trade — if  we  imagine  all  fiscal  barriers  to  be  removed, 
and  all  bounties  to  be  prevented — is,  in  fact,  determined  exclusively 
by  the  desires  of  the  world  of  consumers,  and  the  actual  faculties 
and  opportunities  of  the  producers  in  the  different  countries ;  not 
by  the  proportion  in  which  each  nation  chooses  to  share  its  National 
Dividend  between  producers  and  property -owners.  Each  com- 
munity may,  therefore,  work  out  its  own  salvation  in  the  way  it 
thinks  best.  The  nation  eager  for  progress,  constantly  raising  its 
National  Minimum,  will  increase  in  productive  efficiency,  and  steadily 
rise  in  health  and  wealth.  But  it  will  not  thereby  interfere  with  the 
course  chosen  by  others.  The  country  which  honors  Individual 
Bargaining  may  reject  all  regulation  whatsoever,  and  let  trade  after 
trade  become  parasitic ;  but  it  will  not,  by  its  settling  down  into 
degradation,  gain  any  aggregate  increase  in  international  trade,  or 
really  undermine  its  rivals.1  Finally,  the  nation  which  prefers  to 
be  unprogressive,  but  which  yet  keeps  all  its  industries  self-support- 
ing, may,  if  circumstances  permit  its  stagnation,  retain  its  customary 
organisation,  and  yet  continue  to  enjoy  the  same  share  in  inter- 
national commer;e  that  it  formerly  possessed. 

1  Let  us  suppose,  for  instance,  that  the  capitalists  in  the  United  States  so  far 
strengthen  their  position  as  to  put  down  all  combinations  of  the  wage-earners, 
annul  all  attempts  at  factory  legislation,  and,  in  fact,  prohibit  every  restriction  on 
Individual  Bargaining  as  a  violation  of  the  Constitution.  The  result  would 
doubtless  be  a  proletarian  revolution.  But  assuming  this  not  to  occur,  or  to  be 
suppressed,  and  the  rule  of  the  Trusts  to  be  unchecked,  we  should  expect  to  see 
the  conditions  of  employment  in  each  trade  fall  to  subsistence  level,  and  with  the 
advance  of  population,  stimulated  by  this  hopeless  poverty,  even  below  the 
standard  necessary  for  continued  efficiency.  The  entire  continent  of  America 
might  thus  become  parasitic,  and  successive  generations  of  capitalists,  served  by 
a  hierarchy  of  brain-working  agents,  might  use  up  for  their  profit  successive 
generations  of  degenerate  manual  toilers,  until  these  were  reduced  to  the  level  of 
civilisation  of  the  French  peasants  described  by  La  Bruyere.  But  the  total  inter- 
national trade  of  America  would  not  be  thereby  increased  ;  on  the  contrary,  it 
would  certainly  be  diminished  as  the  faculties  of  the  nation  declined. 


APPENDIX    III1 

SOME  STATISTICS  BEARING  ON  THE  RELATIVE  MOVEMENTS  OF  THE 
MARRIAGE  AND  BIRTH-RATES,  PAUPERISM,  WAGES,  AND  THE 
PRICE  OF  WHEAT. 

IN  connection  with  the  relation  of  the  number  of  births  to  the 
number  of  marriages,  and  the  connection  of  one  or  both  of  these 
with  the  price  of  wheat,  the  amount  of  pauperism,  or  the  rate  of 
wages,  the  following  diagram  and  table  may  be  of  interest. 

We  have  placed  side  by  side  the  number  of  persons,  per  thousand 
of  the  population  in  England  and  Wales,  who  were  married  or  born 
in  each  year  from  1846  to  1895  inclusive;  the  number  simul- 
taneously in  receipt  of  Poor  Law  relief  on  one  day  in  each  of  the 
years  1849  to  1895  inclusive;  and  the  average  recorded  price  of 
wheat  per  imperial  quarter  for  each  year  from  1846  to  1896.  These 
are  the  ordinary  statistics  of  the  Registrar-General's  Reports.  To 
them  we  have  added  the  weekly  wages  from  1846  to  1896  actually 
paid  to  the  engineman  at  a  small  colliery  in  the  Lothians,  taken 
from  the  colliery  books.  Where  the  rate  was  altered  during  any 
year,  the  average  of  the  fifty-two  weekly  rates  of  that  year  has  been 
calculated.  We  have  also  added  columns  showing  the  Trade  Union 
Standard  Rate  for  Stonemasons  in  Glasgow  from  1851  to  1896, 
averaged  in  the  same  manner,  and  that  for  Compositors  in  London 
from  1846  to  1896,  the  latter  (the  "Stab"  or  time  wages)  changing 
so  rarely  that  it  has  been  taken  as  constant  for  each  year.  And  in 
order  to  give  some  rough  idea  of  the  amount  of  real  wages,  to  which 
these  money  wages  have  been  equivalent,  we  have  in  each  case 
reckoned  out  the  "  wages  in  wheat,"  the  amount  of  wheat  that  the 
Lothians  Engineman,  the  Glasgow  Stonemason,  and  the  London 
Compositor  could  have  purchased  each  year  with  a  full  week's  wages. 
This  does  not,  of  course,  express  the  "  real  wages  "  with  any  precision, 

1  See  Part  III.  chap.  i.  "The  Verdict  of  the  Economists." 


874  Appendix  III 

for  whilst  the  price  of  wheat  has  moved  predominantly  in  one 
direction,  the  amount  paid  by  the  workmen  for  meat  and  house-rent 
has  certainly  moved  considerably  in  the  other.  It  must  be  re- 
membered, too,  that  no  allowance  has  been  made  for  "  lost  time," 
periods  of  unemployment,  and  other  deductions.  The  wages  of  the 
Engineman  are  practically  continuous  throughout  the  year.  The 
Stonemason,  on  the  other  hand,  is  necessarily  idle  in  the  months  of 
frost,  and  probably  loses  more,  even  in  the  summer,  by  deductions 
of  one  kind  and  another,  than  he  gains  by  "overtime."  The 
London  Compositor  may  be  either  employed  with  great  constancy, 
or  be  intermittently  out  of  work.  It  does  not  seem  possible  to 
ascertain  whether  these  irregularities  are  greater  or  less  than  in 
past  times.  Nor  can  it  be  assumed  with  certainty  that  the 
wages  at  different  periods  represent  a  payment  for  the  same  labor. 
The  work  of  the  Stonemason  and  the  Compositor  is,  perhaps,  not 
essentially  different  to-day  from  that  of  the  corresponding  classes 
fifty  years  ago  ;  the  higher  standard  of  speed  and  intensity  now 
required  being  set  off  against  the  reduction  of  the  weekly  hours. 
On  the  other  hand,  the  development  of  steam  engines,  and  the  in- 
creased speed  and  complexity  of  their  working,  have  transformed 
the  Engineman  into  a  skilled  and  responsible  mechanic,  who  is  now 
claiming  to  be  a  certificated  professional. 

The    diagram  and    table   of    figures    have    been    prepared    by 
Mr.  F.  W.  Gallon :— 


Persons  married 

per  1000  of  the 

population  living 

in  England  and 


[To  face  page  874.] 


gland  and  Wales, 
and  Wales. 

purchasable  with  the  weekly  wages  of  a  London 
e  Union  Rate. 

urchasable  with   the   weekly  wages  of  a   Glasgow 
e  Union  Rate. 

urchasable  with  the  actual  weekly  earnings  of  an 


COCOCOOOCOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOCOOOCOOOOOCO 


O    t^  i-n  "~»  N  vO    >-"    NvO    rj-oo    o»J~v"^N    O    O    ''I-  N    On^n 
vp^vObxTO<WOOMD^rt-^-"^t^t^vOVOvOt^.OOt^l>.ir> 

d  d  o"  d  d  d  d  6  d  d  6  d  d  6  d  6  o*  d  o*  d  6  d 


OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 


«2  ft  w 


d  d  o 


sp 

',5  bo  w 

"8  g  * 

rt  ? 


d  d  d  d  d  d  d  dodo  o 


•-  c  " 
S  'P.-2 

S  111 

.£      J 


O    OvO"^coot^oo    c^    •-!    coo    O    N    O    n    Oooco 


"•C  ft-S  §    . 

- 


-iOO 


CO  CO  vO    O 


O    w 


<  8* 


vO 


\O  l^oo  OO  "-<  (^  ro^f^ovO  t^OO  OO  ^  n  cO^^nO  t^. 
^^T^^»J^i^"^"^l^l^lJ^1^vr^l-r>vOvOvOvOvOv£)v£>vO 
COCOCX)OOOOCX3000000CX300CXDCOCOOOCOOOOOCX)COOOOO 


OO  ON  O  •"•  M  CO  ^  "~i  vQ  t^CO  ON  O  •"•  M  CO  "xl-  "~>  O  t^  OO  ON  O  >->  M  co  Tf-  "~>  \O 
>sOvO  t^t^r^f^tvxt^tv.t->tvxt^.OOOOOOOOOQOOCOOOOOOO  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON  ON 
OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOCXDOOCOOOOOCOOOCOOOOOOOCOCOOOCOOOOOOOOOOO 


\O    vr>  r*x  -tf-  CO  >-H    vr>  O  OO    fOC^N    1-1    ON  O  vO    •-<    OMD    *•«    CO  *-"    co   co  vQ    ^J-  \O 

J>,OOOO    O    >-i    "-"    "-<    i-i    CJ    t-i    O 


oooooooooooooooooooooooooooo'o 

vOvOvO^OvOvOvOvOvOvOvOvOvOvOvOvOvOvOvOvO^OMDvOOOCOOOOOOOOO 
CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  fO  CO  CO  CO  co  CO  ro  ro  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO 


u->r^OOM    ^  I-"    O    t^H-i 

r^-uoLn-^Loir^vooooo  ts.  m  in  wn  %O  \O  r-^oo   OC^ONOO   ooo   »-<   co«j->vo 
d  d  d  d  d  o*  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  6  d  6  d  d  d  d  «  «  6  M  ^  «  „* 


oo    r^t^lxOO    O    "-*    '^••'^•txvOvOt^ONO    OOOOCNO    O    <-<    <->    M    I-H    n    co 


OO    r^t^t^O"-1    -^J-vO    O    O    t^"-»Lnr>sONi-i    OOOONOO    •-"    M    "->\QvO 
n     N     M     N     n     CO   CO   CO   Tf   Tf   N     tN     W     n     N     COM     N     CJ     M     M     COCOCOCOcOCOCOco 


'Ot^Ni-<oooonMOL'^)-<OOOOO"^ooi<^-t^ 
u-»MDvOvO    mi-Ovq    t^OOOOOOOO    O>O     ON   IH     N     Tj-Tfn 

d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  d  M  d  M  M  M  M  M* 


O    ^f^    OOO    C^vO    O    >-nO    COCOONONM    coco-3-i-i    O    N    COO    O    coco 
O    COOO    O    ONOOCO    •-<    t^vOvOvO    i^u->\OvOO    iJ-vvO    >-i    COCON    cococo 


i-i    !-/•>  Ni-iNi-iONi-itxOvO 
TtCOCOCOCOCOn     COCOCON     M     M 


OOOO    M    O^O    ""O    rJ-coO^O    t-C      ONOO    vo\       ON  OO 


lr-iiii-nv       lvOMD    urt-rt-cococococ      M    M    ^    >-     O    »-     O    O    ONO 
cocococococococococococococococococococococococococonco 


vO 


CO    ONO    >-i    M    co-^t^ovO    t^OO    ON©    "-<    M    cOTj-u->vO    t-xCO    O^  O    >-<    N    co-^-u'%vo 
\OvO    r^I^t-xr^f^t-xt^t^r^r^OOOOOOCQOOOOOOOOOOOO    ONONONONONONON 

ooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooco 


APPENDIX   IV 

A    SUPPLEMENT    TO    THE    BIBLIOGRAPHY    OF    TRADE    UNIONISM 

THE  following  list  of  publications  bearing  on  Trade  Unionism  and 
combinations  of  workmen  has  no  special  connection  with  the  present 
work,  and  must  be  regarded  merely  as  a  supplement  to  the  list,  forty- 
four  pages  in  length,  which  formed  Appendix  VI.  of  the  History  of 
Trade  Unionism.  It  has  been  prepared  in  the  same  manner  as  the 
original  list.  It  accordingly  omits  all  Parliamentary  Papers,  for 
which  the  student  should  consult  the  excellent  classified  catalogues 
issued  by  Messrs.  P.  S.  King  and  Son  of  Westminster ;  it  omits  all 
local  histories  and  records  mentioned  in  the  bibliography  appended 
to  vol.  i.  of  The  Gild  Merchant  by  Dr.  Gross ;  and  it  makes  no 
attempt  to  include  ordinary  economic  works  on  the  one  hand,  or 
trade  histories  on  the  other.  As  before,  we  have  given  the  reference 
number  in  the  British  Museum  catalogue,  whenever  we  have  been 
able  to  find  a  copy  of  the  work  in  that  invaluable  storehouse,  and 
we  have  mentioned  other  libraries  only  when  no  copy  could  be  dis- 
covered at  the  British  Museum. 

For  the  present  work,  even  more  than  for  the  History  of  Trade 
Unionism^  we  have  had  to  go,  not  to  any  regularly  published  books, 
but  to  the  voluminous  internal  literature  of  the  Trade  Unions  them- 
selves, of  which  hundreds  of  publications  are  issued  annually.  These 
are  still  seldom  collected  or  preserved  by  public  libraries,  though 
they  afford  most  valuable  material  to  the  student  of  sociology.  The 
British  Library  of  Political  Science  (10  Adelphi  Terrace,  Strand, 
London;  director,  Professor W.  A.  S.  Hewins)  has  now  been  established 
for  the  express  purpose  of  collecting  these  and  other  materials  for 
sociological  inquiry.  Our  own  considerable  collection  of  manuscript 
extracts  and  printed  documents  relating  to  Trade  Unionism,  com- 
paratively few  of  which  are  mentioned  in  the  following  list,  has  now 
been  deposited  in  this  library,  where  it  can  be  consulted  by  any 
student 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


ABERDEEN,  Papers  relating  to  the  Trades  of,  1777-1818.     Aberdeen  Pub.  Lib. 

Report  on  the  affairs  of  the  Guildry  of.     Aberdeen,  1836.     8vo. 

Aberdeen  Pub.  Lib. 
AGRICULTURAL   and    General    Laborers,    Federal    Union    of.     Report   to   the 

Trade  Societies  and  general  public  of  the  United  Kingdom.     London,  [1874]. 

8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

AKROYD,  EDWARD.      On  the    present   attitude  of  Political  Parties.      London 

[Leeds  printed},  187 4.     8vo.  8138  g. 

ALLEN,  THOMAS.     The  history  and  antiquities  of  London,  Westminster,  South- 

wark  and  parts  adjacent.     London,  4  vols.     8vo.      1827-1829.  2065  a. 

ANSIAUX,  M.     Heures  de  travail  et  salaires,  etc.     Paris,  1896.     8vo. 

08276  k.  i. 

Rapport  sur  la  journee  de  huit  heures  de  travail.      Societe  d'etudes  sociales 

et  politiques.     Bruxelks,  1897.      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

ANSTIE,  J.  [Chairman  to  the  General  Wool  Meeting  in  the  year  1788].  Obser- 
vations on  the  importance  and  necessity  of  introducing  improved  machinery 
into  the  Woollen  Manufactory,  etc.  London,  1803.  8vo.  1138  i.  2  (2). 

APPEAL,  an,  to  Manufacturers  on  the  present  state  of  Trade,  etc.  Birmingham, 
1795.  8vo.  T.  1467  (16). 

an,   to  the  Editors  of  the   Times  in  behalf  of  the  Working  Classes,  etc. 

London,  1845.     8vo.  1390  g.  21. 

APPLEGARTH,  R.  Compulsory  attendance  at  school.  Reprinted  from  the 
Sheffield  Independent.  {London,  1874?]  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

APPRENTICE  LAWS.  Resolutions  of  the  Master  Manufacturers  and  Tradesmen 
of  the  cities  of  London  and  Westminster  on  the  Statute  5  Eliz.  c.  4.  {Lon- 
don, 1814.]  fol.  1882  d.  2. 

ARBITRATION  between  the  North-Eastern  Railway  Company  and  their  work- 
men at  Newcastle-on-Tyne  and  Gateshead,  December  1889,  Shorthand 
notes  of  the.  R.  Spence  Watson,  arbitrator.  MS.,  213  pp.  fol. 

Newcastle-on-Tyne  Lib. 

ASHLEY,  W.  J.  The  Railroad  Strike  of  1894.  [American  Economic  Associa- 
tion.] Cambridge,  Mass.,  1895.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

ASHWORTH,  HENRY.  An  inquiry  into  the  origin,  progress,  and  results  of  the 
strike  of  the  Operative  Cotton-spinners  of  Preston.  Manchester,  1838. 

Foxwell  Coll. 

B.  P.  GENT.  A  help  to  magistrates  and  ministers  of  justice  ;  also  a  guide  to 
Parish  and  Ward  officers,  etc.  London,  1700.  I2mo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 


88o  Appendix  IV 

BALMFORTH,  OWEN.  Huddersfield,  past  and  present.  Huddersfield,  1894. 
8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

BANKS,  THOMAS.  A  short  sketch  of  the  Cotton  Trade  of  Preston  for  the  last 
sixty-seven  years.  \Preston\  1888.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

BARRISTER,  A.  Observations  upon  the  law  affecting  Combinations  and  Trades 
Unions,  and  upon  the  Trades  Union  Bill.  By  a  barrister.  London,  1869. 
8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

BARTON,  JOHN.  Observations  on  the  circumstances  which  influence  the  con- 
dition of  the  laboring  classes.  London,  1817.  8vo.  8275  c. 

A  letter  to  the    Rt.    Hon.    the   Marquis  of  Lansdowne,  etc.       Lambeth, 

1839.      8vo.  8247  bbb.  41. 

BATT,  W.  S.  The  Ship  Constructive  Association,  Portsmouth.  Presidential 
address  ....  at  the  first  annual  general  meeting,  .  .  .  .  24th  April  1884. 
Portsea,  1884.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

The    Ship    Constructive  Association,   Devonport.     Address  by  W.   S.   B. 

....  at  Devonport,  5th  December  1884.     Devonport,  1884.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

BAYES,    W.     Remarks  upon  Archbishop  Whately's  letter  on  Medical  Trades- 
Unions.     London,  1863.     8vo.  739°  aaa. 
BECHTLE,  OTTO.     Die  Gewerkvereine  in  der  Schweiz.    Jena,  1887.     4to.     In 
Elster,  L.  Staatswissenschaftliche  Studien,  etc.     Bd.  2,  Heft  i,  1887,  etc. 

8207  h. 

BIRKS,  JAMES.  Trades  Unionism  ;  a  criticism  and  a  warning,  etc.  Reprinted 
from  the  Newcastle  Weekly  Chronicle.  West  Hartlepool,  1894.  8vo. 

08275,  ee  2I  (I2)' 

BIRMINGHAM  and  National  Trades'  Defence  Association,  Rules  of.  {Birming- 
ham, 1862.]  8vo.  T.U. 

TOWN    COUNCIL.     Reduction    of  wages   in    the    Public   Works   depart- 
ment.    Report    of    the    debate    in    the    Council    on    4th    January    1881. 
Birmingham,  1881.      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

BON  WICK,  JAMES.     Romance  of  the  wool  trade.     London,  1887.     8vo. 

8229  c.  32. 

Second  edition.     London,  1893.      8vo.  08227  g-  46. 

BOOK  OF  TRADES,  The,  or  library  of  the  useful  arts.      Fourth  edition.     London, 

1811.     Three  pts.      I2mo.  7942  a.  55. 

Sixth  edition.     London,  1815.      3  pts.      i6mo. 

7943  a.  3. 
BOOKBINDERS.     Articles  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Journeymen  Bookbinders  of 

London    and    Westminster.      MS.       24th    March    1820.     Printed,    London, 

1828.  Fox  well  Coll. 

Day-working  Society  of,   London.       Report  of  the    Advisory  Committee 

appointed  to  the  duty  of  preparing  a  list  of  the  Jaffray  collection  of  trade  docu- 
ments pursuant   to  a  resolution  of  the  lodge,  July   1882.     London,  [1883]. 
8vo.  National  Liberal  Club  Lib. 

Account  of  receipts  and  expenditure  of  the  dispute  in  the  Metropolitan 

bookbinding  trade,  October  1891   to  December  1892.     London,  1893.       fo1- 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

BOULTON,  S.  B.  The  genesis  of  a  Conciliation  Act.  [Reprinted  from  the 
Chamber  of  Commerce  Journal,  September  1896.]  London,  1896.  8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

BRADFORD.  Protest  of  the  Bradford  Short-time  Committee  against  the  proceed- 
ings of  Mr.  Richards,  the  Factory  Inspector.  Bradford,  1835. 

Foxwell  Coll. 


Bibliography  88 1 

BRASSVVORKERS.  Breeden  v.  Noon.  An  important  point  of  law  to  workmen. 
[Report  of  the  trial  of,  etc.]  Birmingham,  1890.  4to. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

The  Brassworkers'  Year-book,  No.    I   for   1895.     Issued  by  the  National 

Society  of  Amalgamated  Brassworkers.     Birmingham,  1895.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

BRICKLAYERS.  Operative  Bricklayers'  Society.  Metropolitan  Central  Strike 
Committee's  report,  from  nth  April  to  I5th  November  1892.  London,  1892. 
8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

BRIEF  STATE,  a,  of  the  inland  or  home  trade  of  England  ;  and  of  the  oppres- 
sions it  suffers,  and  the  dangers  which  threaten  it  from  the  invasion  of  hawkers, 
pedlars,  and  clandestine  traders  of  all  sorts.  London,  1730.  Svo. 

Guildhall  Lib.,  catalogued  under  Trade. 

BROADHURST,  J.     Political  Economy.     London,  1842.     Svo.  1138,  h.  6. 

BRUSHMAKERS.  A  List  of  Prices  agreed  upon  between  the  Masters  and  Journey- 
men Brush  Manufacturers  in  London,  Friday  I5th  March  1805.  London, 
1805.  Svo.  T.U. 

A  List  of  Prices  agreed  upon  between  the  Masters  and  Journeymen  Brush- 
makers  in  Sheffield  on  the  I7th  June  1825.     Sheffield,  1825.      Svo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

The  Half- Yearly  Returns  of  the  Society  of  Journeymen  Brushmakers,  with 

an  accurate  list  of  the  names  of  every  tramp  relieved  from  the  8th  December 
1828  to  the  8th  June  1829,  etc.     London,  1820.     Svo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

BUCKLEMAKERS.  Appeal  from  the  Buckle  Trade  of  London  and  Westminster 
to  the  Royal  conductors  of  fashion.  London  [1792].  Svo.  1044  h.  28  (5). 

BULLEY,  A.  A.,  and  Whitley,  M.  Women's  Work,  etc.  [Social  Questions  of 
To-day  series,  vol.  13.]  1894.  Svo.  08276  e. 

BUILDERS.  The  Builders'  Price  Book,  containing  a  correct  list  of  the  prices 
allowed  by  the  most  eminent  surveyors  in  London  to  the  several  artificers  con- 
cerned in  building.  [Collected  by  an  experienced  surveyor.]  London  [N.D.] 
Svo.  1029  i.  6  (3). 

BUILDING  TRADES.  [London.]  The  Strike,  Trade  Rules,  Conduct  of  the 
Masters,  etc.  Case  prepared  at  the  request  of  the  Building  Trades  Conference 
by  Mr.  W.  P.  Roberts,  solicitor,  and  opinion  of  Mr.  Edwin  James,  Q.C.,  and 
Mr.  Gordon  Allan.  London,  1859.  8vo.  T.U. 

Report  of  preliminary  conference  on  National  Federation  of  the  Building 

Industry.      Held  at  .    .   .   London,  7th  and  8th  August  1895.     London,  1895. 
Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Birmingham    Master    Builders'  Association.       Reports    and    statement    of 

accounts,  1884,  etc.      (In  progress)  Birmingham,  1885,  etc.  fol.  8282  h. 

BUILDING  TRADES  GAZETTE,  THE  NATIONAL.  A  monthly  journal.  No.  i. 
September  1895.  410.  Issued  by  the  London  Building  Trades  Federation. 

B.M.  (P.P.) 

BUILDING  TRADES  NEWS,  THE.  A  monthly  journal  issued  by  the  London 
Building  Trades'  Federation.  No.  I.  September  1894.  4to.  etc. 

B.M.  (P.P.) 

[BURN,  J.  DAWSON.]  A  Glimpse  at  the  Social  Condition  of  the  Working 
Classes  during  the  early  part  of  the  present  century,  etc.  London  [1868].  Svo. 

8282  aa.  39. 

BURNLEY,  JAMES.  The  history  of  wool  and  wool-combing.  London,  1889 
Svo.  2251  e.  12. 

VOL.  II  3  L 


882  Appendix  IV 

C.  W.  and  M[ATHER]  R[ALPH].  An  impartial  representation  of  the  case  of  the 
poor  Cotton-spinners  in  Lancashire,  etc.,  with  a  mode  proposed  to  the  Legisla- 
ture for  their  relief,  etc.  London,  1780.  8vo.  523  g.  23  (2). 

CABINETMAKERS.  The  prices  of  Cabinet  work,  with  tables  and  designs,  etc. 
London,  1797.  4to.  Birmingham  Library. 

A   Supplement  to  the  London  Cabinetmakers'  Price  Book  of    1797,    as 

agreed  to  in  Birmingham,  1803.     Birmingham,  1803.     4to. 

Birmingham  Library. 

No.    I    Supplement    to  the  Cabinetmakers'   London    book    of  prices,  by 

George  Atkinson  and  William  Somerville.     London,  1805.      4to.      712  k.  14. 

The  Edinburgh  Book  of  Prices    for    Manufacturing  Cabinet   Work,  etc. 

Edinburgh,  1805.      8vo.  Foxwell  Coll. 

The  Portable  Desk  makers'  and  Cabinet  small  workers'  London  Book  of 

prices,  as  settled  at  an  adjourned  meeting  of  the  trade,  1st  September  1806. 
London  [printed  for  the  Society],  1806.      8vo.  7942  c.  29. 

Articles  of  agreement  made  between  the  members  of  the  Society  of  Cabinet- 
makers. . .  in  Birmingham.    Birmingham,  1808.    8vo.      Birmingham  Library. 

The  London  Cabinetmakers'  Book  of  Prices  for  extensible  dining  tables. 

By  a  Committee.     London,  1815.      4to.  712  R-  J4* 

Supplement  to  the   Cabinetmakers'  [of  Edinburgh]  Book   of  Prices,   etc. 

Edinburgh,  1825.      8vo.  Foxwell  Coll. 

The  London  Cabinetmakers'  Book  of  Prices  for  work  not  provided  for  in 

the  Union  Book.      By  a  Committee.      London,  1831.     4to.  7121.  15. 

CALICO  PRINTERS.  Considerations  addressed  to  the  Journeymen,  by  one  of  their 
Masters.  Manchester,  1815.  Manchester  Library. 

Rules  for  the  conducting  of  the  Union  Society  of  Printers,   Cutters,  and 

Drawers  in  Lancashire,  Cheshire,  Derbyshire,  etc.     Manchester,  1813. 

Manchester  Library. 

Report  of  the  Calico  Printers'  Committee  on  Wages.     Manchester,  1831. 

12  pp.  Manchester  Library. 

CARPENTERS.  The  Carpenters  and  Joiners  vade  mecum  and  faithful  guide,  or  an 
authentic  book  of  rates  or  prices,  etc.  London,  1776.  8vo.  1029  i.  6  (5). 

The  London  Standard,  or  a  concise  and  comprehensive  list  of  Carpenters' 

and  Joiners'  prices,  etc.     Duly  considered  and  adjusted  by  a  considerable  and 
respectable  number  of  masters.     London  [printed  for  the  Society  of  Master 
Carpenters],  1778.      8vo.  1029  i.  6  (4) 

Prices  of  Carpenters'  and  Joiners'  work  for  the  present  year.     London, 

1801.     8vo.  1029  k.  14. 

The   Journeymen  Carpenters'   and  Joiners'  guide   to  the  price  of  labor. 

Published  by  order  of  the  Trade.     London,  1811.  Foxwell  Coll. 

Laws  and  Regulations  of  the  Joiners'  Protective  Society.      Instituted   I5th 

February  1832,  and  remodelled  2Oth  May  1842.      Glasgow,  1842.      8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Rules    and    Regulations    of  the    Friendly    Society    of  Operative    House 

Carpenters  and  Joiners,  as  revised  and  agreed  to  ...    1836.     London,  1836. 
8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

1837.  Do. 

• 1838.  Do. 

1840.  Do. 

• 1859.  Do. 

Balance-sheet  of  the  Operative  Carpenters  and  Joiners  of  Manchester  and 

vicinities  Lock-out  from  loth  May  to  6th  November  1866.     Manchester,  1866. 
S.sh.fol.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 


Bibliography  883 

CARTERS.  Report  of  the  Proceedings  and  Transactions  of  the  Glasgow  Carters' 
Committee.  Glasgow,  1835.  Mitchell  Library,  Glasgow. 

CARTWRIGHT,  Dr.,  Memoir  of  the  Life  of.  MS.  1843,  in  Devonshire  Collec- 
tion. Derby  Library. 

CHAIRMAKERS,  etc.  The  London  Chairmakers'  and  Carvers'  book  of  prices  for 
workmanship.  London,  1802.  410.  558  b.  20  (2). 

Supplement    to   the    London    Chairmakers'  and  Carvers'  book  of  prices. 

London,  1808.      4to.  558  b.  20  (3). 

Second  Supplement  to  the  London    Chairmakers'  and  Carvers'  book  of 

prices  ...   by  a  Committee  of  Master  Chair  Manufacturers  and  Journeymen. 
London,  1811.     4to.  712  k.  16. 

CHESTER,  G.  J.  The  voice  of  blood  crying  from  the  ground.  A  sermon  on  the 
late  alleged  trade  outrage.  Sheffield [1861].  8vo.  4277  aaa.  14. 

CHEVALIER,  E.     Les  salaires  aux  xixe   siecle.     Paris,  1887.      8vo. 

08228  h.  10. 

CHICAGO.  Report  of  the  Chicago  Strike  of  June-July  1894.  By  the  United 
States  Strike  Commission.  Washington,  1894.  8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Eugene  v.  Debs  and  others.      Report  of  the  case  of,  ia  the  Supreme  Court 

of  the  United  States.      Chicago  [1894].      8vo.      [By  C.    S.   Darrow,   counsel 
for  petitioners].  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

CHITTY,  J.  A  practical  Treatise  on  the  law  relative  to  apprentices  and  journey- 
men, and  to  exercising  trades.  London,  1812.  8vo. 

6325  aaa.  15. 

CLELAND,  Dr.  J.  Former  and  present  state  of  Glasgow.  [Glasgow  Stat.  Soc.] 
Glasgow,  1836.  Mitchell  Lib.,  Glasgow. 

CLERKS.     The  necessity  for  a  National  Union  of.     London,  N.D.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

COACHMAKERS.  Rules  of  the  Coachmakers'  Society.  Wisbech,  Isle  of  Ely. 
Instituted  1st  May  1827.  Wisbech,  1835.  8vo.  T.U. 

United    Kingdom     Society    of.       Appeal    from    the    delegate    meeting 

assembled  at  Leeds,  June  1848,  to  the  Coachmakers  of  the  three  kingdoms. 
[Leeds]  1848.     8vo.  T.U. 

COALHEAVERS.     The  Coalheavers'  Case  [a  petition  to  the  House  of  Commons]. 

S.sh.fol.  1764.  214  i.  3  (68). 

COBBETT,  W.  Cobbett's  Weekly  Register,  Saturday,  I4th  April  1821.  No.  2 

vol.  39.     To  the   Stocking- weavers  of  Leicestershire,   Nottinghamshire,  and 

Derbyshire,  etc.  Nottingham  Free  Library. 

CONCILIATION,  de  la,  et  de  1'Arbitrage  dans  les  conflits  collectifs  entre  patrons 

et  ouvriers  en  France  et  a  1'etranger.  Office  du  Travail.  Paris,  1893.  410. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

in  Trade  disputes.      Newcastle  Leader  Extra.     Newcastle-on-Tyne,  1894. 

4to.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

COOPERS,  Incorporation  of,  Glasgow.  List  of  Office  Bearers  1890-91,  and 
abstract  of  accounts  for  year  1889-90.  Glasgow,  1870.  8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

COTTON  TRADE.  The  Cotton-weavers'  New  Act  [of  1800]  passed  in  con- 
sequence of  two  petitions  presented  to  the  House  of  Commons,  etc.  Printed 
for  the  use  of  the  petitioners.  Manchester,  1800.  8vo. 

Manchester  Library. 

An  abstract  of  the  Cotton-weavers'  Amended  New  Act  [1804].      By  order 

of  the  Select  Committee  of  Weavers  in  Bolton.     Bolton,  1804.     8vo. 

Manchester  Library. 


884  Appendix  IV 

COTTON  TRADE.  Rules  for  governing  the  Union  of  Weavers  associated  for  the 
purpose  of  obtaining  a  proper  remuneration  for  their  industry,  etc.  Man- 
chester;  1824.  Manchester  Library. 

Manual    Labor    versus    Machinery.      By  the    member    for    Lanarkshire. 

London,  1834.     8vo.     47  pp.  Manchester  Library. 

Report  of  Deputation  to  the  Right  Hon.  H.  Matthews,  Q.C.,  M.P.,  27th 

January    1887,    in    regard    to    Factory    and    Workshop    Inspection.     Also, 
Report  of  Joint  Interview  of  employers  and  employed  with  the  Right  Hon. 
the  Marquis  of  Salisbury,  P.C.,  K.G.,  28th  January  1887,  with  reference  to 
the  Limited  Liability  Acts.     Accringlon,  1887.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Weaving.      Names  of  firms  and  number  of   looms  in  the  districts  com- 
prising   the    Northern    Counties'    Amalgamated    Associations    of    Weavers. 
[Accrington]  1888.     4to.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

—  Weaving.     Report  of   the    Special    Committee  [of  the  Town  Council  of 
Blackburn]  appointed  to  inquire  into  the  subject  of  steaming  in  weaving  sheds. 
Blackburn,  1888.     fol.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

—  List  of  private  firms  and  Spinning  companies  in  each  district  comprising 
the  Oldham  Province,  etc.      Oldham,  1889.     Svo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Sir  Henry  James  and  the  textile  workers.      Presentation  at  ...   Bury. 

Biiry  [1892].      Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Report  of  the  Proceedings  of  the  first  International  Textile  Congress,  held 

at  Manchester,  July  1894.     Manchester  [1894].     Svo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Report  of  the  Second  International  Congress  of  Textile  Workers,  held  in 

Ghent,  Belgium,  August  1895.      Ghent,  1895.      &vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Report  of  the  Case  of  Andrew  Harris  v.  The  Preston  Weavers'  Association 

Judgment.      Preston,  1895.     Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Division  list  of  M.P.'s  who  voted  for  and  against  the  imposition  of  the 

Indian  Import  Duties,  etc.     Issued  by  the  United  Textile  Factory  Workers' 
Association.     Manchester,  1895.      fol.  Brit;  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Indian  Import  Duties.      Issued  by  the  United  Textile  Factory  Workers' 

Association.     Manchester,  1896.      Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Weaving.       Steaming  in  Weaving  sheds.       Demonstration  of  Blackburn 

Weavers.     Blackburn,  N.D.      Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

CROSBY,  B.  Crosby's  Builders'  new  Price  Book.  London,  1806,  etc.  [annually 
to  1854-55].  Svo.  P.P.  2491  m. 

DANBY,  J.     Des  greves  ouvrieres.     Bnixelles,  1884.     Svo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
DAVIS,  C.  T.     Labor  and  Wages.      Washington,  1878.     Svo.       8275  dd  6  (2). 

H.  F.  A.     The  Law  and  Practice  of  Friendly  Societies  and  Trades  Unions 

under  the  Friendly  Societies  Act  1875,  the  Trades  Union  Act   1871,  and  the 
Conspiracy  and  Protection  of  Property  Act   1875,  etc.     London,  1876.      Svo. 

6376  bb. 

DAVIES,  THOMAS.  Prize  Essay  on  the  evils  which  are  produced  by  late  hours  of 
business,  etc.  London,  1843.  Svo.  8276  c.  6l. 

Prize  Essay  on  the  evils  which  are  produced  by  late  hours  of  business,  etc. 

1 3th  eel.     London,  1844.      8vo.  8282  c.  36. 

DECIIESNE,  L.  La  greve  contre  le  tissage  &  deux  metiers  dans  1'industrie  lainiere 
de  Verviers  en  1895-1896.  Verviers,  1897.  Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 


Bibliography  885 

DEFENCE  of  the  Working  Classes,  in  reply  to  an  article  in  Chambers's  Edinburgh 

Journal,  entitled  "Strikes,  their  Statistics."     London,  N.D.      8vo. 

Foxwell  Coll. 
DEHN,    P.       Arbeiterschutzmassregeln  gegen    Unfall-   und   Krankheitsgefahren. 

Berlin,  1882.      8vo.  8277  f.  16  (12). 

DELONEY,  THOMAS.     The  History  of  John  Winchcomb,  usually  called  Jacke  of 

Newberie,  the  famous  clothier.      [Edited  by  J.  O.  Halliwell],     London,  1859. 

4to.  12612  g.  19. 

DEW,  GEORGE.     Government  and  municipal  contracts  fair  wages  movement.     A 

brief  history.      London,  1896.     8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

DOCK  Laborers'  Strike  1889,  the  Great,  Manifesto  und  Statement  of  Accounts. 

An  epitomised  history.     London,  1889.     Large  8 vo.     Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
DOHERTY,  JOHN.     A  letter  to  the  members  of  the  National  Association  for  the 

protection  of  labor.     Manchester,  1831.      24  pp.  Foxwell  Coll. 

DOXFORD,   W.    T.      [Engineer   and   Shipbuilder].      Memorandum  of  proposed 

evidence  to  be  given  before  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor,  by  W.  T.  D.   .   .   . 

re  the  Board  of  Conciliation  for  the  Wear  Shipbuilding  Trade,     fol.     N.D. 

or  imprint.     [1892?].  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

DRAGE,  GEOFFREY.     The  Labor  Problem.     London,  1896.     8vo. 

08277  h.  18. 

The  Unemployed.     London,  1894.      8vo.  08275  ee.  5. 

DRURY,  JOHN.      Reply  of  the    Committee  of  the   General    United    Grinding 

Branches  of  Sheffield  and  its  vicinity  to  Earl  Fitzwilliam's  speech  delivered  at 
the  Cutlers'  Feast,  1844.     Sheffield,  1844.      Svo.  Sheffield  Library. 

DUBLIN.    Committee  on  Combinations.    Letter  to  the  Committee  lately  appointed 
on  combinations.      By  a  workman  and  employer.     Dublin,  1827.      Svo. 

8146  bb.  34  (7). 

Letter  to  employer  and  employed.      By  a  manufacturer.     Dublin,  1827. 

Svo.  8146  bb  34  (7). 

Collection  of  documents  relating  to  the  trade  clubs  of  Builders,  Shoemakers, 

Smiths,  Tailors,  and  Weavers,  etc.  in  Dublin.     Circa  1720  etc. 

839  m  23  and  1890  e  5. 

DUNSFORD,  MARTIN.      Historical  Memoirs  of  the  town  and  parish  of  Tiverton 

in  the  County  of  Devon,  etc.      Exeter,  1790.      Svo.  2066  d.  (i). 

DYER,  H.     The  evolution  of  industry.     London,  1895.     8vo.  08277  h.  i. 

EDINBURGH.     Collection  of  documents  relating  to  the  Edinburgh  Trades  Societies' 
Agitation  for  Reform  in  1830-1832.  808  m.  16. 

Chamber  of  Commerce  and  Manufactures.      Memorandum  on  Strikes  and 

Labor  Disputes.     Edinburgh,  1890.     fol.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

EMPLOYERS'  Liability,  Past  and  Prospective  Legislation,  with  special  reference  to 
"  Contracting-Out,"  etc.      Reprinted  from  The  Sun.     London,  1896.     4to. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

The  Workers'  Tragedy,  etc.     Reprinted  from  the  Daily  Chronicle.    London, 

1897.     4to.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

ENGINEERS.     The  Laws  of  the  Friendly  Society  of  Operative  Metal  Workers. 
London,  1834.      1 6  pp.  Foxwell  Coll. 

Rules  of  the  private  donation  fund  of  the  Steam-engine  Makers'  Society. 

Manchester,  1848.      6to.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers.      Balance  Sheet  and  List  of  Subscribers 

to  the  Newton  testimonial.     London,  1862.      Svo.         Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Sheffield   Strike  of  Engineers.      Balance  Sheet  for  the  7th  week,  ending 

1 8th  August  1873.     Sheffield,  1873.     8vof  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science, 


886  Appendix  IV 

ENGINEERS.     Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers.      Rules  of  the  Society  from 
1847101892.    Reprinted  1892.    London,  1892.    410.      Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers.      Report  of  the  Executive  Council  on 

the  Financial  Position  of  the  Society,  with  statistics  and  diagrams.     London, 
1895.     8vo-  B"t.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers.      Statistics  of  Rates  of  Wages  and  Lists 

of  Corresponding  Officers,  etc.  1895.     London,  1895.     Oblong  8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers.     Report,  re  the  Government  and  Fair 

Contracts.     London,  1895.      8vo.  T.U. 

Amalgamated  Society  of  Engineers.      Report  on  Dockyard  Administration. 

London,  1895.     8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

ENQUIRY,  an,  into  the  management  of  the  poor.   [Anon.]    London,  1767.     8vo. 

104  n.  28. 

an  [into  the  causes  of  poverty,  etc.,  Anon.].     London  [1795  ?]     8vo. 

8275  d.  I  (I). 

—  an,   into  the  state  of  the  manufacturing    population.      [Anon.]     London, 

1831.     8vo.  T.  1351  (13). 

ENTICK,  J.     A  new  and  accurate  history  and  survey  of  London,  etc.     4  vols. 

London,  1766.      8vo.  290  f.  22-25. 

FACTORY  ACTS.     Answers  to  certain  objections  made  to  Sir  Robert  Peel's  Bill, 

etc.     Manchester,  1819.     8vo.  Foxwell  Coll. 

FELKIN,   W.     Facts  and  calculations  illustrative   of  the  present  state  of  the 

Bobbin  Net  Trade.     Nottingham,  1831.      8vo.  Nottingham  Library. 
Remarks  upon  the  importance   of  an  inquiry  into  the  amount  and  appro- 
priation of  wages  by  the  working  classes.      London,  1837.      8vo. 

Nottingham  Library. 
An  account  of  the  Machine- wrought  Hosiery  Trade.     [A  paper  read  before 

the  British  Association    i8th  September  1844.]     Reprinted.     London,  1845. 

8vo.  Nottingham  Library. 

FERRARIS,  C.   F.     Gli  infortuni  sue  lavoro,  e  la  legge.     Roma,  1897.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

II  materismo  storico  e  lo  state.      Palermo,  1897.      8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
FIELDEN,  S.     The  Turn-out  of  the  Master  Mechanics.     A  letter  to  the  Times. 

Bolton,  1852.      8vo.  Manchester  Library. 

FOUCCROULLE,  G.     Les  Conseils  de  Conciliation.     Bruxelles,  1894.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
Fox,  Stephen  N.,  and  Black,  Clementina.     The  Truck  Acts — what  they  do  and 

what  they  ought  to  do.      London,  1894.      8vo.  08282  g.  5  (7). 

FRANKENSTEIN,    K.      Der  Arbeiterfrage   in   der   Deutschen    Landwirthschaft. 

Berlin,  1893,     8vo.  08276  k.  22. 

Der  Arbeiterschutz,  seine  Theorie  und  Politik.     Leipzig,  1896.     8vo. 

8009  k. 
FREE   LABOR  CONFERENCE,  verbatim    report   of  the,   held  .  .  .  June   1894. 

London,  1894.      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

FREE   LABOUR    GAZETTE,     THE.      The   organ   of  the  National    Free    Labor 

Association.     London  (weekly),  1895-1896,  etc.  fol.       Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
FRENCH  POLISHERS.     Alliance  and  West-end  Metropolitan.    Guide  to  members 

in  search  of  employment,  of  firms  paying  the  minimum  rate  of  wages  and  over. 

London,  1889.      8vo.  8247  a.  54. 


Bibliography  887 

FRIENDLY  Societies.     Collection  of  Rules  of,  etc. 

Manchester  Library  (368-372.) 

GALTON,  F.  W.  (Editor).     Workers  on  their  Industries.     London,  1894.     8vo. 

08275  e-  26. 

Select    documents    illustrating    the   history   of  Trade  Unionism.      I.  The 

Tailoring  Trade.      London,  1896.      8vo.  08207  f- 

GIBSON  v.  LAWSON.  Report  of  the  proceedings  in  the  Supreme  Court  of  Judi- 
cature. Gateshead  {printed},  1891.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

GILBERT,  J.  T.  Calendar  of  Ancient  Records  of  Dublin  in  the  possession  of 
the  municipal  corporation  of  that  city.  Dublin,  1889,  etc.  8vo. 

'     10390  i.      (In  progress.) 

GIRDLESTONE,  C.  The  South  Staffordshire  colliery  district.  Its  evils  and 
their  cure.  London  \Stourbridge,  print ed\,  1855.  8vo.  8282  d.  28. 

A  Letter  to  the  .   .   .   Bishop  of  London  ...  in  reference  to  the  meeting 

of  the  landowners  and  employers  of  labor  in  the  metropolis,  holden  on  ... 
29th  April  1863.     London  [1863].      8vo.  4107  bb.  41. 

GLASGOW.  Address  of  the  United  Trades  Committee  appointed  in  aid  of  the 
Miners,  to  the  various  organised  bodies  in  Scotland  and  elsewhere.  Glasgow, 
1856.  4to.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

GLASS  BOTTLE  MAKERS.  Answers  to  the  Schedule  of  Questions  issued  by 
the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor.  [Reprinted  from  C.  6795-ix.].  Castle- 
ford,  1892.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Minutes    of   evidence    taken    before    the    Royal    Commission    on    Labor. 

[Reprinted  from  C.  6894-ix.].      Castkford,  1893.      8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Fifth  Report  of  the  International  Union  of.      London,  1893.     ^vo- 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

A  Report  of  Conference  of  the  Yorkshire  Glass  Bottle  Manufacturers  and 

the  Glass  Bottle  Makers  on  the  Wages  Question,  etc.      1893.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

A  Report  of  the  Rates  of  Wages,  Lists  of  Numbers,  Rates  of  overwork 

and  working  regulations  of  the  Glass  Bottle  Makers  of  G.  B.  and  I.  for  1895. 
[Castleford],  1895.     60  pp.      8yo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

GLASSMAKERS.  Articles,  Rules,  Orders,  and  Regulations  of  the  Friendly 
Society  of  Glassmakers.  .  .  .  Lemington.  Established  loth  January  1789. 
Newcastle,  1829.  8vo.  8275  bb.  4. 

An  earnest  appeal  from  the  furnace,  by  a  bottle  hand  to  his  fellow-work- 
men, etc.     London,  [1856].      8vo.  8435  a.  108  (2). 

GLOTIN,  HYACINTH  E.  Etude  historique,  juridique  et  economique  sur  les 
syndicats  professionels.  Paris,  1892.  8vo.  54o6  de.  10. 

GOVERNMENT  SERVANTS.  Statement  by  the  extra  out-door  officers  of  the  Port 
of  London,  with  reference  to  their  hours  of  work,  pay,  and  general  conditions. 
London  [1890].  fol.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Statement    of  grievances    of   Government    Employees,   submitted    to    the 

Parliamentary    Committee    of    the    Trades    Union    Congress,    January    1895. 
London,  1895.     8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

GRAND  National  Consolidated  Trades  Union  of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland,  Rules 
and  Regulations  of  the,  etc.  London,  1834.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

GREEN,  C.  H.  Employers'  Liability,  its  History,  Limitations,  and  Extension. 
London,  1897.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

J.  L.      The  rural  industries  of  England.     London,  1895.      8vo. 

08276  g.  73. 


888  Appendix  IV 

GREG,  W.  R.  Essays  on  political  and  social  science,  etc.  2  vols.  London, 
1853.  8vo.  2238  c.  8. 

GUTTERIDGK,  J.  R.  The  disease  and  the  remedy.  An  essay  on  the  present 
state  of  the  working  classes  ;  including  a  true  description  of  the  degraded 
character  of  our  railway  laborers.  London,  1852.  I2mo. 

8275  a.  6 1  (10). 

J.     Lights  and  shadows  in  the  life  of  an  artisan.      Coventry,  1893.     8vo. 

10827  aaa.  45. 

HALE,  W.  A  letter  to  Samuel  Whitbread,  Esq.,  M.P.,  containing  observations 
on  the  distresses  peculiar  to  the  poor  of  Spitalfields,  etc.  London,  1816.  8vo. 

1103  h.  30. 

An  address  to  the  manufacturers  of  England  on  the  causes  which  have  led  to 

the  unparalleled  calamities  of  our  manufacturing  poor.    London,  1826.     I2mo. 

T.  1131  (13). 
HALL,  LEONARD.     The  old  and  new  Unionism.     Manchester,  1894.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

HALLAM,  W.     Miners'  Leaders.      Thirty  portraits  and   biographical  sketches. 

London,  [1894].      8vo.  10803  aaa.  33. 

HARDING,  W.     The  history  of  Tiverton.     2  yols.      Tiverton,   1845-47.     8vo. 

2066  b. 

HARRISON,  FREDERIC.     Workmen  and  the  Law  of  Conspiracy.      [Tracts  for 

Trades  Unionists,  No.  2].     London,  1874.      8vo.  8282  cc.  I. 

HERKNER,  H.     Die  sociale  Reform  als  Gebot  des  wirtschaftlichen  Fortschrittes. 

Leipzig,  1891,     8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

-  Die  Arbeiterfrage.      Berlin,  1894.      8vo.  08276  i.  40. 

HOLLAND,  JOHN.     The  history  and  description  of  fossil  fuel,  the  collieries  and 

coal  trade  of  Great  Britain.      London,  1835.      8vo.  7261.  40. 

2nd  edition.      London,  1841.      8vo.  726  i.  14. 

HOLROYD,    J.    B.    [Earl   of   Sheffield].       Observations  on    the    manufactures, 

trade,    and    present    state    of    Ireland.       2    parts.       London,    1785.     8vo. 
Many  other  editions.  1102  h.  14  (5). 

HOOLE,  H.  A  letter  to  the  Rt.  Hon.  Lord  Viscount  Althorp,  M.P.,  in  defence 
of  the  Cotton  Factories  of  Lancashire.  Manchester,  1832.  8vo. 

Foxwell  Coll. 

A  Report  of  the  proceedings  on  the  conviction  of  Benjamin  Taylor,  John 

Ball,    W.    Rutherford,    and  James  Snow,  part    of  the  Framework  Knitters' 
Committee.     Nottingham,  1821.  Nottingham  Libraiy. 

A  statement  of  prices  for  making  and  repairing  stocking-frames,  etc.  June 

1838.      Derby,  1838.  Nottingham  Library. 

-  The  Framework  Knitters'  Trial,  in  the  Exchequer  Chamber,  before  fifteen 
judges  of  the  land.  Archer  v.  James,  Channer  v.  Cummings,  and  the  Truck 
Act,  etc.  Nottingham^  1861.  Nottingham  Libraiy. 

HOWITT,  W.      The  rural  life  of  England.      2  vols.     London,  1838.     8vo. 

2366  c.  9. 

The  Rural  and  Domestic  Life  of  Germany,  etc.      London,  1842.      8vo. 

f  2364  e.  6. 

INGLIS,  J.  [Engineer  and  Shipbuilder].  Memorandum  on  the  apprentice 
question.  Presented  to  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor.  Glasgow,  1892. 
fol.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Memorandum  of  evidence  proposed  to  be  given  before  the  Royal  Commis- 
sion on  Labor  ...   on  demarcation  of  work,   and  on  picketing.      Glasgow, 
N.P.     FoL  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 


Bibliography  889 

INGLIS,  J  The  Apprentice  Question.  Glasgow,  1894.  Brit.  Li.").  Pol.  Science. 
INSTRUCTIONS  for  masters,  traders,  laborers,  etc.  In  four  parts,  to  masters, 

traders,    and    laborers ;     apprentices   and    servants ;    youth ;     and    children. 

London,  1699.  I2ino.  8410  b.  38. 

Another  edition.  London,  1718.  I2tno.  8410  aa.  33. 

IRELAND.  A  Digest  of  the  evidence  taken  before  Select  Committees  of  the  two 

Houses  of  Parliament  appointed  to  inquire  into  the  state  of  Ireland,  1824-25. 

London,  1826.  Haliday  Tracts,  vol.  1335.  Royal  Irish  Academy. 

IRON  and  STEEL  WORKERS.  South  Wales.  Memorandum  of  agreement 

[between  employers  and  workmen,  as  to  joint  Board  and  Sliding  Scale  for  the 

Industry].      Cardiff,  1890.     fol.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

South  Wales.     Memorandum  of  agreement  [between  employers  and  work- 
men as  to  joint  Board  and  Sliding  Scale  for  the  industry].     Ebbw  Vale,  1893. 
fol.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

IRONMOULDERS    OF    SCOTLAND,   Associated  Society   of,  Evidence   before   the 

Labor  Commission,  June  1892.      Glasgow,  1892.      8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
IRON  TRADE,   North  of  England.      Report  of  arbitration  case  before  Messrs. 

Williams  and  Mundella,  February  and  March   1876.      From  the  Ironworkers* 

Journal,  in  the  volume  of  MS.  etc.  relating  to  arbitration  in  the  Iron  Trades, 

in  the  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 

Board     of    Arbitration    and    Conciliation.      Report    of   discussion 

before   the   arbitrator   at   Darlington,   July   1877.     Darlington,   1877.     4to. 
26  pp.  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 

Board  of  Arbitration  and  Conciliation.     Report  of  discussion  before 

the    arbitrator  at  Darlington,  April  1878.     Darlington,  1878.      15  pp.     4to. 

Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 
Board  of  Arbitration  and  Conciliation.     Arbitration  proceedings  at 

Darlington  on  the  Wages  Question.      December  1878.     Darlington,   1879. 

19  pp.      410.  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 
Board  of  Arbitration  and  Conciliation.      Report  of  discussions  before 

the  arbitrator  at  Darlington,  August  and  October,  1879.      Darlington,  1879. 

21  pp.      4to.  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 
Board  of  Arbitration  and  Conciliation.      Report  of  Board  meeting 

held  in  Darlington,  May  1880,  to  hear  Mr.  Waterhouse's  explanation,  etc. 

Darlington,  1880.      12  pp.      8vo.  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 
Board  of  Arbitration  and  Conciliation.      Claim  by  the  workmen  in 

plate  and   sheet  mills  for  a  return   of  the   7^  per    cent  (special)   reduction, 

27th  November  1880.     Darlington,  1881.     29  pp.      8vo. 

Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 
Board  of  Arbitration  and  Conciliation.      Presentation  to  Mr.   David 

Dale,  J.P.   at  Darlington,  4th  October  1881.     Darlington,    1881.      12  pp. 

8vo.  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 
Board  of  Arbitration  and  Conciliation.      Report  of  discussions  before 

the    arbitrator    at    Middlesbrough,    April    1882.  Darlington    [printed]. 

24  pp.     4to.  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 
Board  of  Arbitration  and  Conciliation.      Report  of  discussion  before 

the   arbitrator  at   Middlesbrough.      November    1882.     Darlington   [printed] 

1882.      II  pp.     4to.  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 
Board    of    Conciliation    and    Arbitration.       Rules,    By-laws,    and 

Instructions.     Middlesbrough,  1883.      8  pp.  8vo. 

Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 
•*•- Board  of  Conciliation  and  Arbitration.     Report  of  discussion  before 


890  Appendix  IV 

the  Arbitrator  at  Newcastle,  4th  January  1884.     Darlington  [printed]   1884. 

20  pp.      4to.  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 

IRON  TRADE,  North  of  England.    Board  of  Conciliation  and  Arbitration.    Report 

of  discussion  before   the  arbitrator  at  Newcastle,   April  1884.       Darlington. 

[printed}  1884.      14  pp.      4to.  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 

Board  of  Conciliation  and  Arbitration.     Report  of  discussion  before 

the  arbitrator  at  Newcastle,  November  1884.       Darlington  [printed}   1885. 

17  pp.      4to.  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 
Board  of  Conciliation   and  Arbitration.      Wages  arbitration  before 

R.  S.  Watson,  Esq.,  LL.D.     Court  held  at  Newcastle-on-Tyne,  October  1885. 

Darlington  [printed}  1885.      23  pp.     4to.  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 
Board   of  Conciliation  and   Arbitration.      Wages  arbitration  before 

R.  S.  Watson,  Esq. ,  LL.D.    Court  held  at  Newcastle-on-Tyne,  November  1888. 

Darlington  [printed'}  1 888.      12  pp.      4to.  Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 
Statement  showing  the  average  net  selling  price  of  manufactured  iron 

and  the  relative  wages  [for  puddling]  from  1876  to  1885.     fol. 

Newcastle-on-Tyne  Library. 

Description  of  the  Consett  Iron  Works.     Neivcastle-on-Tyne,  1893. 

<.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

IRWIN,  M.  H.     The  conditions  of  women's  work  in  laundries,  etc.      Glasgow, 

1894.     fol.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Women's  employment  in  shops.      Report  of  an  inquiry  conducted  for  the 

National  Federal  Council  of  Scotland  for  Women's  Trades.      Glasgow,  1896. 
fol.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Home  work   amongst  women.      Report  of  an  inquiry  conducted  for  the 

Glasgow  Council  for  Women's  Trades.      Glasgow  [1897].     fol. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
ITHURIEL.     First  prize  essay  on  Trades  Unions.      Glasgow,  1875.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

JACKSON,    S.    and    Milner,  J.      The   evidence    of,    on    the   state  of  Trade  in 

Sheffield,    given    before    the    Royal    Commission    on     Manufacturers,    1833. 

Sheffield,  1833.      8vo.  Sheffield  Library. 

JEANS,  J.  S.     Conciliation   and   arbitration    in   labor   disputes,  etc.     London, 

1894.     8vo.  08276  f.  8 1. 

JEFFREY,  F.  [afterwards  Lord].     Substance  of  the  speech  of  ...  at  the  public 

dinner  given  at  Edinburgh  to  Joseph  Hume,    Esq.,    M.P.,    iSth  November 

1825.      Edinburgh,  1825.     8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

JOURDAN,  F.  S.      De  1' Assurance  obligatoire  centre  les  accidents  du  travail  en 

Allemagne.      Paris,  1894.      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

JUBB,  SAMUEL.     The  history  of  the  shoddy  trade,  etc.    London  [Bat ley  printed} 

1860.      I2mo.  7943  b.  5- 

JUSTITIA,  M.  [pseud,  i.e.  John  Frearson].     The  relative  rights  and  interests  of 

the  employer  and  the  employed  discussed,  etc.     London,  1855.      8vo. 

8276  b.  35. 

An  essay  .   .   .   showing  how  the  surplus  funds  of  the  Amalgamated 

Society    of   Engineers    may  be  practically  applied    to    associated   productive 
purposes.     London  [1855].      8vo.  8226  a.  63  (2). 

KATZENSTEIN,  L.     Die    Lohnfrage    unter   dem    Englischen  Submissionswesen. 
Berlin,  1896.      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

KAUTSKY,  K.     Das  Erfurter  Programm.     Stuttgart,  1892.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 


Bibliography  891 

KAY,  J.  P.  The  moral  and  physical  condition  of  the  working  classes  employed 
in  the  cotton  manufacture  in  Manchester.  London,  1832.  8vo. 

8276  de  13.  (10). 

KEUFER,  A.  Rapport  tendant  a  rechercher  les  moyens  de  parer  aux  funestes  con- 
sequences du  systeme  actuel  des  adjudications.  [Pour  la  Federation  Fra^aise 
des  travailleurs  du  libre].  Paris,  1896.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

LABOUR   AND   THE    POOR.      Extracts  reprinted   from  the  Morning  Chronicle, 

1850.     London,  1850.      8vo.  8276  de.  14. 

LABOUR  JOURNAL,  the  official  organ  of  the  Hull,  Grimsby,  and  Goole  Trades 

Councils.      Monthly,  1894-1896.     4to.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

LANGFORD,  J.  A.     A  century  of  Birmingham  life.     2  vols.     Birmingham,  1868. 

8vo.  2368  e. 

LAW  of  Intimidation,  The.     What  does  it  mean  ?     Reprinted  from  the  Western 

Daily  Mercury.     Plymouth,  1890.     8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

LAWS  Concerning  Trade  and  Tradesmen.     London,  1712.      I2mo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

LECKY,  W.   E.   H.     Democracy  and  liberty.     2  vols.     London,    1896.     8vo. 

2238  cc.  15. 
LETTER,  a,  to  the  members  in  Parliament  on  the  present  state  of  the  coinage. 

With  proposals  etc.      London,  1771.     8vo.  T.  933  (15). 

a,  to  a  member  of  Parliament  on  the  importance  of  liberty  etc.      London, 

1745.     8vo.  Foxwell  Coll. 

LEVASSEUR,  E.  Histoire  des  classes  ouvrieres  en  France,  etc.  2  vols.  Paris, 
1859.  8vo.  2240  d.  7. 

Les  corporations  et  la  liberte  du  travail  [cours  d'economie  industrielle,  etc. 

Association  Poly  technique  de  Paris].     Paris,  1866,  etc.     8vo.  ac.  4417. 

LEVY,  J.   H.      The  economics   of  labor  remuneration.     London  [1894],  8vo. 

08275  ee.  21  (14). 

LLOYD,  H.  D.     Wealth  against  commonwealth.     London,  1894.     8vo. 

8282  cc.  46. 

LOCH,  D.  Letters  concerning  the  trade  and  manufactures  of  Scotland,  par- 
ticularly the  woollen  and  linen  manufactures.  Second  edition  with  large 
additions.  Edinburgh,  1774.  4to.  8246  g.  7. 

Third  Edition.     Edinburgh,  1774.      8vo.  8247  b.  32. 

Fourth  Edition.     Edinburgh,  1775.     4to.  8246^8. 

Essays  on  the  trade,  commerce,   manufactures,  and  fisheries  of  Scotland, 

etc.      3  vols.     Edinburgh,  1778-79.      I2m.  8227  aa.  42. 

LONDON.  The  privileges  of  the  free  artificers  of  the  city  of  London  defended  ; 
in  an  appeal  to  the  committee  appointed  to  receive  the  complaints  of  the 
masters  of  the  several  manufactures  in  the  city  against  their  journeymen. 
London,  N.D.  [1750?].  8vo.  Guildhall  Lib.  [catalogued  under  Free]. 

LONDON  Trades  Council,  The.  Report  of  the  deputation  to  the  London  School 
Board  relative  to  the  printing  contract,  October  1886.  London,  1886.  8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

LOWELL,  J.  S.  Industrial  Arbitration  and  conciliation,  etc.  New  York,  1893. 
8vo.  08276  g.  57. 

MACDONNELL,  G.  P.  The  industrial  future  and  the  prospects  of  the  working 
classes.  London,  1886.  8vo.  4018  c. 

MAC!LWAINE,  J.  H.  [Engineer  and  Shipbuilder],  Memorandum  of  evidence 
proposed  to  be  given  before  the  Royal  Commission  on  Labor,  by,  ...  on 
strikes,  overtime,  apprentices,  hours  of  labor,  demarcation  of  work,  fluctua- 
tions of  wages,  etc.  fol.  N.D.  W.  Coll. 


892  Appendix  IV 

MAHAIM,  E.      Etudes  sur  1'association  professionelle.     Liege^  1891.     Svo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Les  syndicats  professionnels.     Bruxelles  [1892?].     Svo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

MANCHESTER.  A  collection  of  police  documents  relating  to  Manchester. 
Circa  1780  etc.  fol.  1856.  Manchester  Library. 

The  chief  constable's  accounts,  1854  etc.  Manchester  Library. 

MANN,  T.  What  a  compulsory  eight  hour  working  day  means  to  the  workers. 
London  [1886].  Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

—  Presidential  address.     [To  the  delegate  meeting  of  the  Dockers'  Union  at 
Hull,  1892].     London  [1892].      Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

and  Tillett,    B.     The  new  Trade   Unionism.      A  reply  to  Mr.   George 

Shipton.      London  [1892].      Svo.  8282  cc.  47  (3). 

MARTIN,    R.     Die   Ausschliessung   der  vcrheirateten  Frauen  aus  der  Fabrik. 

Eine  Studie  an  der  Textil-Industrie.      Tubingen,  1897.     Svo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
MARTINEAU,  Harriet.     On  the  tendency  of  sticks  and  strikes  to  produce  low 

wages.      London,  1834.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

MARTIN-SAINT-LEON,  E.     Histoire  des   corporations  de  metiers,  etc.     Paris, 

1897.     Svo.  W.  Coll. 

MATHER,  W.     The  forty-eight  hours'  week.     A  year's  experiment  and  its  results 

at  the  Salford  Iron  Works,  Manchester.     Manchester,  1894.      Svo. 

8282  ff.  12  (14). 

A  reply  to  some  criticisms  on  Mr.  Mather's  report  of  a  year's  trial  of  the 

forty-eight  hours' week.     London,  1894.      Svo.  8282  ff.  12(15). 

MINERS.  Report  of  the  proceedings  at  a  public  meeting  held  at  the  London 
Tavern,  24th  February  1818,  to  take  into  consideration  the  best  means  of 
alleviating  the  condition  of  the  distressed  miners  in  different  parts  of  the 
kingdom.  8276  ee.  60. 

Miners'  wages  and  price  of  furnace  coal  for  the  last  twenty  years.      Tipton, 

1884.     S.sh.  fol.      Issued  by  the  West  Bromwich  etc.   Amalgamated  Associa- 
tion of  Miners.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

South  Staffordshire  and  East  Worcestershire  Coal  and  Ironstone  Miners' 

Wages  Board  and  Sliding  Scale  Agreement.     [Dudley}  1890.     Fol. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
The  Royal  Commission  on  mining  royalties.      Evidence  of  Mr.  S.  Woods. 


Reprinted  from  the  Wigan  Observer,  i6th  May  1891.      Wigan,  1891.     4to. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Durham   Coal   Trade  Arbitration    Cokemen,    1891.      Newcastle-on-Tyne, 

l%9l>  352  PP-      8vo.  Dr.  R.  S.  Watson's  Collection,  Newcastle-on-Tyne. 

Derbyshire  Miners'  Association.  A  Report  by  Dr.  J.  Court  of  the  Examina- 
tion of  the  eyes  of  coal  miners  working  in  collieries  in  Derbyshire  using  both 
safety  lamps  and  naked  lights.  Chesterfield,  1891.  Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Minutes,  Circular  Reports,  etc.,  of  the  Durham  County  Mining  Federation 

Association.      Vol.  II.      From  1891  to  1894.     Durham,  1894.     Svo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Northumberland  Miners'  Gala,  July  7th,  1894.      Speeches  by  members  of 

Parliament.      Address  by  the  Bishop  of  Durham.     Newcastle,  1894.      Svo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Miners'  Conciliation  Board.     Minutes  of  proceedings  at  a  Joint  Conference. 

.   .   .   Tuesday,  3rd  April  1894.      Lord  Shand  in  the  Chair.      [No  imprint. 
N.D.].      Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Board  of  Conciliation  for  the  Durham  Coal  Trade.     Report  of  proceedings 


Bibliography  893 

30th  April  and  1st  May  1895.      The  Rt.   Hon.   Lord  Davey  in  the  Chair. 
Newcastle-on-Tyne,  1895.     8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

MINERS.  Board  of  Conciliation  for  the  Durham  Coal  Trade.  Report  of  pro- 
ceedings 23rd  September  and  4th  October  1895.  The  Rt.  Hon.  Lord  Davey 
in  the  Chair.  Durham,  1896.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

The  Sixth  International   Miners'    Congress.       Held   at  ...    Paris,  June 

1895.      Report  of  Proceedings.      London,  1895.      8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Miners'  Federation  of  Great  Britain.     Report  on  Mines  Eight  Hours'  Bill. 

London,  1895.     8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Mines  Eight  Hours'  Bill.     Report  of  a  deputation  to  the  Most  Hon.  the 

Marquis  of  Salisbury,  K.G.,  and  the  Right  Hon.  Arthur  J.   Balfour,  M.P., 
I4th  March  1895.      London,  1895.      8vo-  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

The  Blackwell  Colliery  Company's  Coals  and  their  treatment.      Reprinted 

from  Coal  and  Iron,  loth  February  1896.     London,  1896.      8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

MORTIMER,  T.  The  universal  director ;  or  the  nobleman  and  gentleman's  true 
guide  to  the  masters  and  professors  of  the  liberal  and  polite  arts  and  sciences, 
and  of  the  mechanic  arts  manufactures  and  trades,  established  in  London,  etc. 
London,  1743.  8vo.  Guildhall  Lib. 

Another  copy.      London,  1763.      8vo.  10349  c.  3. 

MOSES,  E.  and  Son.     The  growth  of  an  important  branch  of  British  industry. 

The  ready-made  clothing  system.     London,  1860.      8vo.  8244  b.  29. 

MUSEE  SOCIAL,  LE  (PARIS).  See  the  valuable  series  of  "circulars"  published 
since  January  1896  on  the  principal  events  in  the  Labor  Movement. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

NARRATIVE  and  exposition  of  the  origin,  progress,  principles  and  objects  of  the 
General  Association  for  the  purpose  of  benefiting  the  manufacturing  and 
agricultural  laborers.  London,  1828.  8vo.  Foxwell  Coll. 

NASH,  VAUGHAN.     Trade  Unionists  and  co-operation.     London,  N.D.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

NEVE,  R.  The  city  and  country  purchaser  and  builder's  dictionary ;  or  the 
compleat  builder's  guide.  London,  1703.  8vo.  7820  bb. 

Several  other  editions. 

NEVILL,  JOHN.     Seasonable  Remarks  on  the  Linen  Trade  of  Ireland.     Dublin, 

1783.  Haliday  Tracts,  vol.  461,  Royal  Irish  Academy,  Dublin. 

NEWBIGGING,  T.     Lancashire  characters  and  places.     Manchester,  1891.     8vo. 

10360  d.  26. 

NIELD,  D.     Addresses  to  the  different  classes  of  men  in  the  parish  of  Saddle- 
worth.      1795.     8vo.  Foxwell  Coll. 
NORTHHOUSE,  W.  S.     Coal  Combination,  etc.     London,  1839.     8vo. 

8282  dd.  20  (3). 

NOTTINGHAM  Date  Book,  The.     Nottingham,  1880.  Foxwell  Coll. 

NUNQUAM  [R.  BLATCHFORD].     The  living  wage.     London,  1894.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

OASTLER,  R.     Sketch  of  the  life  and  opinions  of  R.  O.     Leeds,  1838.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
OLDROYD,  M.  A  living  wage.  [London],  1894.  8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

OLIVER,  G.  History  of  the  Holy  Trinity  Guild  at  Sleaford,  etc.  Lincoln, 
1837.  8vo.  4784  d.  23. 


894  Appendix  IV 

OLIVER,  T.     A  new  picture  of  Ne\vcastle-on-Tyne.     Newcastle,  1831.      I2mo. 

796  b.  31. 

PAGAN,  J.  Glasgow  past  and  present.  [Edited  by  J.  P.].  Glasgow,  1851 
etc.  8vo.  10370  e. 

Various  other  editions. 

PARE,  W.     The  claims  of  capital  and  labour,  etc.     London,  1854.     8vo. 

8206  b.  7. 

PEEL,  F.  The  risings  of  the  Luddites,  Chartists,  and  Plug-drawers.  Brig- 
house,  1895.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

PERCIVAL,  T.  A  letter  to  a  friend  occasioned  by  the  late  disputes  between  the 
checkmakers  of  Manchester  and  their  weavers.  Halifax,  1758. 

Manchester  Library. 

PERCY,  S.  and  R.  London  :  or  interesting  memorials  of  its  rise,  progress, 
and  present  state.  3  vols.  London,  1823.  I2mo.  578  a.  18. 

PHILLIPS,  W.  A.  Labor,  land,  and  law  ;  a  search  for  the  missing  wealth  of 
the  working  poor.  New  York,  1886.  I2mo.  08277  ff.  5. 

PICKARD,  B.  and  Hartford,  E.  Labor  questions.  Speeches  to  the  Eighty 
Club.  London  [1894].  8vo. 

PIDGEON,  D.     An  engineer's  holiday,  etc.     2  vols.     London,  1882.     8vo. 

10025  bbb.  4. 

PLAN  of  a  relieving  fund  for  the  prevention  of  future  encroachments  and  reduc- 
tions of  wages.  Printed  by  order  of  the  meeting  on  Platt  Hill.  July  6th, 
1795.  8vo.  Foxwell  Coll. 

A  practicable  and  eligible,  to  secure  the  rights  and  privileges  of  mechanics ; 

with  proper  directions  for  the  journeymen  whereby  they  may  get  an  advance- 
ment in  their  wages  without  loss  of  time  or  hindrance  of  business,  etc. 
London,  1776.  8vo.  1029  i.  6.  (6). 

PLASTERERS.  List  of  prices  agreed  to  at  a  general  meeting  of  Master  Plas- 
terers. London,  1796.  8vo.  1029  k.  14. 

PLAYFAIR,  W.  A  letter  to  the  Right  Honourable  and  Honourable  the  Lords 
and  Commons  of  Great  Britain  on  the  advantages  of  apprenticeships.  London, 
1814.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

PLUMER,  T.  Speech  of  T.  P.  addressed  to  the  Committee  of  the  House  of 
Commons  [on  the  Woollen  Trade],  1803.  1803.  8vo.  Foxwell  Coll. 

POSTMEN.     The  postmen's  case  for  inquiry.     London  [1894].      8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

POTTERS.  Articles  of  the  Potters'  Independent  Friendly  Society.  Newcastle. 
1837.  8vo.  8275  bb.  4. 

POWELL,  J.  A  letter  ...  on  the  general  influence  of  large  establishments  of 
apprentices,  etc.  London,  1819.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

PRICE,  JOHN.  [Engineer  and  Shipbuilder].  Memorandum  on  the  demarcation 
of  work,  also  on  overtime  and  freedom  of  labor.  Presented  to  the  Royal 
Commission  on  Labor.  Glasgtnv,  1892.  Fol.  W.  Coll. 

PRINTERS.  The  brotherly  meeting  of  the  masters  and  workmen  -  printers. 
Begun  25th  November,  1621  .  .  .  and  hath  been  continued  ...  to  this 
present  fourth  of  May,  1680.  London,  1680.  S.sh.  fol.  1871  e.  9  (57). 

An  Account  of  the  Rise  and  Progress  of  the  dispute  between  the  Masters 

and  Journeymen  Printers  exemplified  in  the  trial  at  large,  etc.     London,  1799. 

Foxwell  Coll. 

. Address  of  the  Compositors  of  Edinburgh   to  the  Master  Printers,  at  a 

General  Meeting  of  the  Compositors  of  this  City  under  authority  of  the  Sheriff. 
Edinburgh,  1803.  Foxwell  Coll. 


Bibliography  895 

PRINTERS,  Edinburgh.     Memorial  for  the  Compositor  Printers,  28th  Feb.  1804. 

Foxwell  Coll. 
Additional  Memorial  for  the  Compositor  Printers,  I2th  May  1804. 

Foxwell  Coll. 
Report  in  the  Process,  by  Robert  Bell,  2Oth  November  1804. 

Foxwell  Coll. 

The  Petition  of  David  Ramsay  for  the  Master  Printers,  23rd  Jan. 

1805.  Foxwell  Coll. 

Answers  for  the  Compositors  to  the  Petition  of  the  Master  Printers, 

9th  February  1805.  Foxwell  Coll. 

Scale  of  Compositors'  Prices  agreed  to  by  the  Master  Printers  in  Glasgow, 

1st  May  1815.      Glasgoiv,  1815.      S.sk.      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Rules  and  Regulations  of  the  London  Union  of  Compositors.     London 

[1840].      I2mo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

London  Society  of  Compositors.-    Report  of  the  Committee  on  the  System 

of  working  adopted  in  each  Office.      London,  1891.      8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Memorandum  of  Agreement  between  the  Economic  Printing  and  Publish- 
ing  Company,  Limited,  and   the   London  Society  of  Compositors,    London, 
1892.     8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

London    Society   of   Compositors    and    Government    Printing    Contracts. 


London,  1894.      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

London  Society  of  Compositors.      [Report  on]  forty-eight  hour  working 

week  and  Federation.     London,  1894.      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

London  Society  of  Compositors  and  the  Linotype.     London,  1894.      8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Printing  Trades'  Federation,  The.      An  appeal  for  justice  to  the  delegates 

of   the   London    Trades   Council,   re  the   Salvation   Army.      London,    1895. 
8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

London    Society  of  Compositors.       Provisional    Agreement    re   Machine 

Scale.     London,  1896.      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Federation  Frangaise  des  travailleurs  du  livre,  fondee  en  1881.      Statuts 

modifies  au  congres  typographique  de  Marseilles,  Septembre   1895.       Paris, 
1896.     8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

PROCEEDINGS  of  the  Third   Congress  of  the  Association   of  all  classes  of  all 
Nations,  held  in  Manchester,  May  1838.     [Manchester},  1838.     8vo. 

Foxwell  Coll. 


RAAIJMAKERS,  C.     Verzekering  tegen  Werkloosheid.    Amsterdam,  1895.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

RENAULT,  C.     Histoire  des  greves.     Paris,  1887.      I2mo.  082756.  13. 

RICHARDSON,  M.  A.  Descriptive  companion  through  Newcastle-upon-Tyne 
and  Gateshead.  Newcastle,  1838.  8vo.  10352  aaa.  12. 

Varioiis  other  editions. 

E.   The  National  Agricultural  Laborers'  Union  Melody  Book.      Original 

Hymns  and  Songs.     Aylesbury,  1874.      32mo.  IJ647  a.  80  (8). 

J.   L.   C.      Employment  of  females  and    children  in    factories  and  work- 
shops, etc.     Dnnedin  [New  Zealand}  1881.     Svo.  8275  cc.  15  (4). 

RICHMOND,  A.  B.  Narratives  of  the  condition  of  the  manufacturing  population 
and  the  proceedings  of  Government  which  led  to  the  State  trials  in  Scotland 
,  .  .  for  administering  unlawful  oaths  in  i8i7>  etc.  London  [printed*]  Glas- 
gow, 1825.  Svo.  809  h.  13. 


896  Appendix  IV 

RICHMOND,  A.  B.  Trial  for  libel,  etc.,  Richmond  v.  Simpkin  Marshall  and 
others.  {Glasgow,  1834?].  8vo.  8135  bb.  (2). 

ROCHETIN,  E.  La  Caisse  Nationale  de  prevoyance  ouvriere,  et  1'intervention 
de  1'Etat,  etc.  Paris,  1894.  I2mo.  08275  f.  16. 

Les  Assurances  ouvrieres    mutualites   centre  la   maladie,  1'incendie   et  le 

chomage.      Parts t  1896.      8vo.  08275  e-  4& 

ROGERS,  F.  The  art  of  bookbinding,  etc.  London,  1894.  8vo.  Pam.  94. 
ROLLE,  John.  The  trader's  safeguard,  etc.  London,  1822.  121110.  515  b.  28. 
ROMILLY,  Sir  S.  Memoirs  of  the  life  of,  etc.  3  vols.  London,  1840. 

1130  d.  39. 
Other  editions. 

ROPEMAKERS'  Friendly  Society,  Articles  and  Regulations  of  the  Associated, 
Glasgow,  Instituted  nth  September  1824.  Glasgow,  1837.  8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
ROUSIERS,  P.  de.     La  question  ouvriere  en  Angleterre.     Paris,  1895.     8vo. 

08275  ee.  40. 

English    edition,   translated    by    F.    L.    D.    Herbertson.     London,    1896. 

8vo.  108277  h.  14. 

[Editeur].     Le  Trade  Unionisme  en  Angleterre,  etc.     Paris,  1896.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 


SCHMID,  C.  A.  Beitriige  zur  Geschichte  der  gewerblichen  Arbeit  in  England 
wahrend  der  letzten  50  Jahre.  In  Elster  L.  staatswissenschaftliche  Studien, 
etc.  Jena,  1896.  8vo.  8207  h. 

SCHMOLE,  J.  Die  socialdemokratischen  Gewerkschaften  in  Deutschland,  seit 
dem  Erlasse  des  Socialesten-Gesetzes.  Jena,  1896.  8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

SCHMOLLER,  G.  Zur  Geschichte  der  Deutschen  Kleingewerbe  im  19.  Jahr- 
hundert.  Halle,  1870.  12010.  8244  bb.  36. 

Jahrbuch  fur  Gesetzgebung  Verwaltung  und  Volkswirtschaft.    Leipzig,  1871, 

etc.  (continued).  P.P.  1385  e. 

SCIIOENHOF,  J.  Wages  and  trade  in  manufacturing  industries  in  America  and  in 
Europe.  New  York,  1884.  8vo.  8275  cc.  14  (7) 

The    industrial    situation    and    the    question    of   wages.      New    York  and 

London,  1885.     8vo.  8275  bbb.  50. 

The  economy  of  high  wages.     New  York  and  London,  1892.      8vo. 

08276.  f.  66. 
SCHULZE-GAEVERNITZ,  G.  von.  The  Cotton  Trade  in  England  and  on  the 

Continent.  Tr.  London,  1895.  8vo.  W.  Coll. 

SCHWIEDLAND,  E.  Kleingewerbe  und  Hausindustrie  in  Osterreich.  2  vols. 

Leipzig,  1894.     8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Vorbericht  iiber  eine  gesetzliche  Regelung  der  Heimarbeit.      Vienna,  1896. 

4to.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Un    projet    de    loi    frangais   sur    de  soi-disant    Conseils    de    Conciliation. 

Paris,  1896.      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

SCOTTISH  Trades   Union  Congress,  Report  of  the  First  Annual.      Held  in  ... 

Glasgow,  March  1897.  Glasgow,  1897.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

SEAMEN.  Evidence  in  favor  of  the  seamen  given  by  J.  Beveridge  of  North 

Shields  before  a  Select  Committee  of  the  House  of  Commons,  loth  July  1825. 

North  Shields,  1826.  8vo.  8275  bb.  4. 

• Representation  of  Seamen  on  Pilotage  Boards,  the.  A  paper  read  at  the 

Seamen's  Congress,  Cardiff,  1889.      1889.      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 


Bibliography  897 

SEILHAC,   L.  de.      La  greve  de  Carmaux  et  la  verrerie  d'Albi.      Paris,    1897. 

8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

SERIOUS  Considerations  addressed  to  British  laborers  and  mechanics  at  the 

present  crisis.  London,  1803.  8vo.  104  g.  44(17) 

SETTLE,  A.  The  meaning  of  the  labor  movement.  Manchester,  1893.  8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
SEVERN,  M.  The  miner's  evangel.  A  text-book  for  all  manual  workers. 

Fontypridd,  1895.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

SHIPBUILDING  TRADES.  The  shipwrights'  vade  mecum,  etc.  London,  1805. 

8vo.  716  d.  24. 

of  the  River  Thames.     A  scale  of  prices  for  job  work  on  old  ships,  care- 
fully arranged  and  compiled  [by  a  committee  of  journeymen].     London,  1825. 
8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Conference    on    Apprentice    Question    held    at    Newcastle-on-Tyne,    i8th 

May  1893,  between  members  of  the  Employers'  Federation  of  the  Shipbuilding 
and  Engineering  Trades  and  the  Representatives  of  the  Boilermakers'  and  Iron 
and  Steel  Shipbuilders'  Society.  Newcastle,  1893.  8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Minutes    of   Line    of  Demarcation  Joint  Committee  of   Shipwrights  and 

Joiners,    which    met    on   Monday    2nd    October    1893,    and    following    days. 
Glasgow,  1894.     Large  8vo.     285  pp.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Employers'    Handbook    in    the  Shipbuilding  and   Engineering  Trades  at 

Newcastle-on-Tyne,  1894.     Newcastle,  1894,      Sm.  8vo. 

Agreements  between  the  Employers'  Association  and  the  Boilermakers  and 

Iron  and  Steel  Shipbuilders'  Society.     Newcastle,  1894.      8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

SHIRLEY,  S.      Our  national  sinews,  etc.     London  [1855].     8vo.      8276,  A.  65. 

SHOEMAKERS,  Dublin.  A  poem  in  honor  of  the  Loyal  Society  of  Journeymen 
Shoemakers  who  are  to  dine  at  the  Castle,  in  Castle  Street,  on  Monday,  25th 
October  1725.  By  R.  Ashton.  Dublin,  1725.  S.sh.  fol.  839  m.  23  (88). 

A  poem  in  honor  of  the  Loyal   Society  of  Journeymen  Shoemakers,  etc. 

By  R.  Ashton.     Dublin,  1726.     S.sh.  fol.  839  m.  23  (155). 

A  dialogue  between  a  brogue   maker   and    the   journeymen    shoemakers. 

Dublin,  N.D.  [1730?].     S.sh.  fol.  839  m.  23  (101). 

Articles  of  the  Journeymen  of  the  City  of  Edinburgh.      Established  1727. 

Edinburgh,  1778.      8vo.  Foxwell  Coll. 

London  Statement  of  Wages.      Established  1st  May  1812.      London,  1812 

1 6  pp. 

SILK  manufacture.      Reasons  for  renewing  the  office  of  Silk  Dyeing. 

816  m.  12  (96). 

Weavers.      The  case  of  the   Silk  and  Worsted  Weavers  in  a  letter  to  a 

member  of  Parliament.     Dublin,  1749.      8pp.      Haliday  tracts.     Vol.  221. 

Roy.  Irish  Academy. 

An  account  of  the  proceedings  of  the  Committee  of  the  Journeymen  Silk- 
weavers  of  Spitalfields  in  the  legal  defence  of  the  Acts  of  Parliament  granted  to 
their  trade.      London,  1823.      67  pp. 

Rules  and  regulations  adopted  by  the  Macclesfield  Silk  Trade  Board,  etc. 

Maccles field,  1849.      J36  pp.     8vo.  1400  b.  35. 

Six  Prize  essays  on  labor  and  wages.     Leicester,  1849.  Manchester  Library. 

SMART,  H.  R.      Trade  Unionism  and  politics.      Manchester,  1893.      8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Miners'  wages  and  the  sliding  scale.      Glasgow,  1894.      8vo. 

8282  ff.  12(17). 
VOL.  II  3  M 


898  Appendix  IV 

SMART,  W.     On  women's  wages.     Glasgow,  1892.     8vo.     Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Studies  in  Economics.      London,  1895.     Svo. 

SMITH,  E.  J.  The  new  Trades  Combination  movement.  Its  principles  and 
methods.  Birmingham,  1895.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

J.  T.       Nollekens    and    his    times,  etc.      2  vols.      London,    1828.       8vo. 

Various  other  editions.  2032  b. 

STRIKE  or  Legislate?     An  appeal  to  Trade  Unionists.     Liverpool,  1894.     Leaf- 
let.    8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
SYKES,  J.     Local  Records  .  .  .  of  Durham  and  Northumberland,  etc.    Newcastle^ 
1824.     8vo.  797  g.  26. 
Various  other  editions. 

TAILORS  [London].  A  true  account  of  the  case  between  the  Worshipful  the 
Master,  Wardens,  and  Court  of  Assistants  of  the  Company  of  Merchant 
Taylors  of  the  City  of  London,  and  the  Master  Working  Taylors,  freemen  of 
this  city,  and  members  also  of  the  said  Company.  London,  1687.  S.sh. 
fol.  Guildhall  Library. 

The  case  of  the  Master  Cutting  Taylors  and  all  other  Master  Workers  duly 

qualified  in  the  Taylory  trade  within  the  cities  of  London  and  Westminster, 
etc.      London,  N.D.  1702-1714.      S.sh.  fol.  Guildhall  Library. 

The  Tailors.      A  tragedy  for  warm  weather ;  in  three  acts.     As  it  is  per- 
formed at  the  Theatre  Royal  in  the  Haymarket.     London,  1778.     8vo. 

643  e.  8  (2). 

An  appeal  to  the  Operative  Tailors  of  Scotland.      By  a  fellow-workman. 

N.D.  1880.     Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Tailors,  Woollen-drapers,  etc.      See  the  collection  of  documents  relating  to 

these  trades.  816  m.  14. 

TAYLOR,  Wm.     An  answer  to  Mr.  Carlile's  Sketches  of  Paisley.     Paisley,  1809. 

Mitchell  Library,  Glasgow. 

W.  C.      Notes  of  a  tour  in  the  manufacturing  districts  of  Lancashire,  etc. 

London,  1842.      Svo.  792  b.  4. 

TEMPERTON  v.  Russell  and  others,  The  case  of,  an  examination  of  its  bearing 
upon  the  rights  of  combination,  etc.   London,  1895.   8vo.    Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
THACKRAH,  C.  T.     The  effects  of  the  principal  arts,  etc.     Leeds,  1831.     Svo. 

1039  1.  28. 

THOM,  W.  Rhymes  and  recollections  of  a  handloom  weaver.  London.  Aber- 
deen [printed],  1844.  Svo.  14^S  c.  49. 

Other  editions. 

TILLKTT,  B.  Address  on  man's  individual  responsibility.  London,  1892. 
Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

The    help    yourself  gospel ;    or,  the    New  Trades    Unionism.       Dundee 

[pointed],  N.D.     Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

The  legislature  and  labour.      An  address.      Cardiff  [printed],  N.D.      Svo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
TRADE  Unionism,  the  tyranny  of.      Reprinted  from  the  Globe.     London,  1894. 

Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

TRADES  Union  Congress.      Parliamentary  Committees'  Report  on  the  Employers' 

Liability  Bill.      London,  1894.     Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
Parliamentary  Committee,  the  Report  of  Important  Deputations  to  Cabinet 

Ministers.      I3th,  I4th,  and  I5th  November  1895.     London,  1895.      Svo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
TURGOT,  A.  R.  J.      CEuvres  .   .   .    Nouvelle  edition  classee  par  ordre  de  matieres 

etc.      Par  E.  Daire.     Two  vols.     Paris,  1844.      Svo.  139°  k.  5-6. 


Bibliography  .      899 

TYLOR,  L.  Old  Age  Allowances.  [The  Central  Association  for  dealing  with 
distress  caused  by  mining  accidents.]  Cardiff,  1895.  4to. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

UNEMPLOYMENT.  Report  of  the  committee  appointed  at  a  public  meeting  at 
the  city  of  London  Tavern,  2nd  May  1826,  to  relieve  the  manufacturers,  etc. 
London  [1829],  by  W.  H.  Hylett.  Foxwell  Coll. 

Rapport  sur  la  question  du  chomage  presente  au  nom  de  la  commission 

permanente.     Paris,  1896,  410.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

UNITED  Kingdom  Alliance  of  Organised  Trades.  Rules  for  the  government  of 
the,  as  adopted  at  the  Conference  held  in  Manchester.  Jamiary  1867. 
Sheffield  [printed],  1867.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

UPHOLSTERERS,  London  West  End  Trade  Society.  Report  of  the  committee 
on  Co-operative  Production,  appointed  November  1894.  London,  1895.  8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

VALERA,   P.      L'insurregione   chartista  in   Inghilterra.     Milano,    1895.     8vo. 

9525  aaa.  27. 
VANDERVELDE,  E.  DE.     Enquetes  sur  les  associations  professionelles  d'artisans  et 

ouvriers  en  Belgique.    2  vols.    Bruxelles,  1891.     8vo.     Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 
VOICE  from  the  aliens,  a,  about  the  anti-alien  resolution  of  the  Cardiff  Trades 

Union  Congress.     London  [1896].      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

VOLTA,  R.  D.      Le  forme  del  salario.     Firenze,  1893.      8vo.  08275  f.  18. 

Le  coalezioni  industriali.     Firenze,  1894.      8vo.      Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

WARD,  BENJAMIN.  The  state  of  the  woollen  manufacture  considered,  etc. 
London,  1731.  8vo.  H39J-  2. 

JOHN.     The  Borough  of  Stoke-upon-Trent.     London,  1843.     8vo. 

1302  1.  i. 

W.  G.     Capital  and  Labor.     Nottingham,  1874.      8vo.  8277  bbb.  5. 

WATERMEN.     The  case  of  the  keelmen  of  Newcastle,  etc.     [London,   1712?] 

S.sh.fol.  8223  e.  9  (31). 

The  case  of  the  poor  skippers  and  keelmen  of  Newcastle,  truly  stated,  etc. 

[London,  1712?]     S.sh.fol.  82236.  9(32). 

A  farther  case  relating  to  the  poor  keelmen  of  Newcastle.      [London,  1712?] 

fol.  8223  e.  9  (32). 

Warning  to  the  keelmen  [of  Newcastle]  by  the  Magistrates.      [Against  a 

strike  and  Riots].     Newcastle,  1822     S.sh.fol.  1879^2. 

Lightermen's  work  and  wages.   Arbitration  by  Lord  Brassey,  K.C.B.   Award 

.   .   .  of  the  umpire,  etc.     London,  1889.     fol.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

The  award  and  conditions  of  service  under  which  the  lightermen.   ...   of 

the  River  Humber  met  work.     The  award  of  E.   N.  Hill  and  J.   D.  Welch, 
arbitrators.     Hull  [1890].      I2mo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

Report   of  a  Conference   between  Representatives  of  the   Association  of 

Master  Lightermen  and  of  the  Amalgamated  Society  of  Watermen  to  consider 
Lord  Brassey's  award,  etc.      London,  1889.      8vo.  T.U. 

WATTS,  J.  The  catechism  of  wages  and  capital,  London.  Manchester  [printed}, 
1867.  I2mo.  8206  a.  38  (5). 

The  working  man  :  a  problem.     Manchester  [1875].     8vo. 

8276  aa.  38  (5). 
WAUGH,  MANSIE,  Tailor  in  Dalkeith.  The  life  of,  written  by  himself,  [by  D. 

M.  Moir].  Edinburgh,  1828.  I2mo.  N.  550. 

WEILER,  J.  La  conciliation  industrielle  et  le  role  des  meneurs.  Bmxelles,  1892. 

Svo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 


QOO  Appendix  IV 

WEILER,J.  Vivons-noussurunvolcan?  Bruxelles,  1893.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

L'esprit  d'autorite  et  la  conciliation  industrielle.      Bruxelles,  1894.     8vo. 

Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

WHITE,  G.      A  digest  of  the  minutes  of  evidence  taken  before  the  committee  on 
Artisans  and  Machinery.      London,  1824.     8vo.  1044  h.  16. 

Abstract  of  the  Acts  repealing  the  laws  against  combinations  of  workmen, 

etc.     London,  1824.      8vo.  8275  b. 

WHITE  SLAVERY.     A  collection  of  pamphlets  on  the  Factory  Acts,  Poor  Law, 

etc.,  1818  to  1837.  1 6  vols.  Foxwell  Coll. 

WOLF,  J.  Sozialismus  und  Kapitalistiche  gesellschaftsordnung,  etc.  Stuttgart, 

1892.  8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 

WOLFF,  H.  W.  Employers'  Liability,  what  ought  it  to  be?  London,  1897. 

8vo.  8276  d.  65. 

WOOLLEN  TRADES.  [A  collection  of  tracts  upon  wool  and  the  woollen  trade], 

London,  1782-1818.      8vo.  B.  547. 

A  copy  of  some  of  the  reasons   formerly  offered  by  the  Gloucestershire 

clothers  to  show  the  true  cause  of  the  decay  of  the  Worcester  trade.     N.  D. 

Foxwell  Coll. 

An  abstract  of  the  grievances  of  trade  which  oppress  our  poor.      Humbly 

offered  to  the  Parliament.     London,  1694.      8vo.  104  g.  44. 

Articles   of  agreement  made,  concluded,  and  agreed  upon  by  the   Royal 

Society  of  Worsted  Weavers  in  the  city  of  Norwich  and  county  of  the  same, 
23rd  Nov.  1717.   Corrected  and  amended,  1 2th  Feb.  1725-26.  Norwich,  1826. 

Articles  of  agreement  made,  concluded,   and  agreed  upon  by  the  Royal 

Society  of  Worsted  Weavers  in  the  city  of  Norwich  and  county  of  the  same. 
23rd  Nov.  1717.     Corrected  and  amended  I2th  Feb.  1725-26. 

Verses  addressed  by  the  Union  of  Trowbridge  to  their  brother  operatives. 

Trowbridge,  S.sh.  foL      N.D.  772  i.  I  (21). 

The  case  of  the  weavers  of  the  city  of  Coventry.      [Coventry,  1720?]     fol. 

357  b.  3  (i 08). 

The  Procurator  Fiscal  v.  the  Woolcombers  of  Aberdeen,  1762. 

Foxwell  Coll. 

Considerations  on   the  woollen  manufactory  of  Ireland.      By  a  friend  to 

Ireland.     Dublin,  1785.  Foxwell  Coll. 

Considerations  upon  a  Bill  now  before  Parliament  for  repealing  (in  sub- 
stance) the  whole  code  of  laws  respecting  the  woollen  manufactures  of  Great 
Britain,   etc.     [By  the  clothworkers  or  shearmen  of  the  counties  of  Wilts, 
Somerset,  York,  and  Gloucester].      London,  1803.      8vo.  1102  i.  89. 

Observations  on  woollen  machinery,  1803.  Foxwell  Coll. 

An  address  to  the  inhabitants  of  Rochdale  and  its  vicinity  on  the  subject  of 

the  present  differences  between  the  weavers  and  their  employers.      Rochdale, 
1829.      12  pp.  Foxwell  Coll. 

Two  letters  of  G.    Poulett  Scrope,  M.P.,  to  the  chairman  of  the  central 

committee  of  the  Handloom  Worsted  Weavers  of  the  West  Riding  of  York, 
with  their  answers  to  the  same.     Bradford,  1835.  Foxwell  Coll. 

The  miseries  of  the  miserable,  or,  an  essay  towards  laying  open  the  decay 

of  the  fine  woollen  trade,  and   the  unhappy  condition  of  the  poor  Wiltshire 
manufacturers.      By  a  gentleman  of  Wilts,  1739.  Manchester  Library. 

A  vindication  of  the  Broad  Cloth  Weavers,  being  the  journeymen's  answer 

to  Mr.  Textor's  letter  in  the  sixteenth  Censor.     Dublin,  1 749.     8  pp.     Haliday 
Tracts,  vol.  221.  Roy.  Irish  Academy, 

WOMEN'S  WORK.      Report  of  investigations  into  the  conditions  of.     Women's 
Co-operative  Guild.     Manchester,  1896.      8vo.  Brit.  Lib.  Pol.  Science. 


INDEX 


ABATTOIRS,  municipal,  ii.  788 
Aberdeen,  combinations  in,  336 
Abinger,  Lord,  367 
Abraham,  May  (Mrs.    Tennant),   329, 

350 

Absentee  employers,  296 

Abstinence,  ii.  623 

Accident  benefit,  152,  170 

Accidents,  long  indifference  to,  355  ; 
working  rules  against,  358  ;  lead  to 
agitation  for  Employers'  Liability, 
368 ;  frequency  of,  374,  376  ;  com- 
pensation for,  378,  388,  390  ;  inquiry 
into,  378,  384,  390 

Accumulation  of  capital,  causes  influ- 
encing the,  ii.  610-632,  871 

Accumulative  vote  in  Coalminers'  con- 
ferences, 45  ;  at  Trade  Union  Con- 
gress, 277  ;  absence  of,  in  Federation 
of  Engineering  Trades,  ii.  523 

Act  of  God,  356,  379 

Activities  in  relation  to  wants,  ii.  697, 
704 

Acton,  Lord,  59 

Actuarial  difficulties  of  competing 
unions,  113  ;  increased  by  Direct 
Legislation,  61,  115;  affected  by 
legal  position  of  Trade  Unionism, 
154  ;  not  yet  properly  studied,  156 

Administration,  at  first  by  whole  body 
of  members,  3  ;  in  times  of  war  by 
secret  committees,  9 ;  by  general 
mass  meetings,  10  ;  by  a  governing 
branch,  12  ;  by  specialised  officers, 
1 6,  27  ;  by  a  Cabinet,  30,  39,  43  ; 
by  a  Representative  Executive,  47  ; 
need  for  specialisation  of,  59  ;  pro- 
gressive centralisation  of,  88-103; 
function  of  the  branch  in,  100 

Admiralty  dockyards,  ii.  554  ;  analogy 
to  Wage  Fund  of,  605 ;  minimum 
wage  of,  775 


Adulteration  Acts,  ii.  734 

Aged,  Trade  Union  provision  for  the, 
152-172  ;  allowed  to  work  below 
Standard  Rate,  165  ;  compulsory  in- 
surance for,  objected  to,  ii.  529  ; 
pensions  for,  not  objected  to,  827 

Agricultural  land,  exhaustion  of,  ii.  752 

Agriculture,  excluded  from  Workmen's 
Compensation  Act,  388  ;  yearly 
hirings  in,  431  ;  supplied  idea  of 
Wage  Fund,  ii.  605  ;  decay  of,  761  ; 
a  Poor  Law  industry,  788 

Alexander  the  Coppersmith,  ii.  564 

Alien  immigrants,  desire  for  exclusion 
of,  252  ;  effect  of,  ii.  744 

Allan,  William,  no,  133,  134,  167, 
170 

Alliances,  the  Birmingham,  ii.  577,  665, 
806 

Altrincham  Stonemasons,  78 

"Amalgamated,"  for  societies  so 
termed,  see  under  the  respective 
trades 

A malgamated Engineers'  Month ly Jour- 
nal, 133;  ii.  514,  515,  524,  563 

Amalgamation,  attractiveness  of,  109  ; 
in  the  building  trades,  109 ;  among 
the  Coalminers,  109 ;  among  the 
Clothworkers,  109  ;  among  the  En- 
gineers, 1 10 ;  difficulties  as  to  basis 
of,  in;  objections  to,  no,  128; 
gradual  differentiation  of,  from  federa- 
tion, 129-141 ;  of  trade  and  friendly 
benefits,  157 

America,  early  use  of  Referendum  in,  19 ; 
boot  and  shoe  factories  in,  398,  413  ; 
trusts  in,  448 ;  ii.  582,  709 ;  nail 
mills  in,  754  ;  possible  future  of,  872 

Andrew,  .Samuel,  449 

Annual  election,  of  officers,  16 ;  advo- 
cated as  democratic,  36  ;  leads  to 
permanence  of  tenure,  16,  50 ; 


QO2 


Index 


abandoned,  40 ;  of  executive  com- 
mittee causes  weakness,  17 

Annual  hirings,  431  ;  relation  of,  to 
Wage  Fund,  ii.  618 

Ansiaux,  Maurice,  324 

Appenzell,  3 

Apprenticeship,  ii.  454-481  ;  literature 
as  to,  454  ;  to  the  journeyman,  455  ; 
custom  of  patrimony  with  regard  to, 
460,  478  ;  statute  of,  454  ;  connection 
of,  with  Doctrine  of  Vested  Interests, 
563  ;  effect  of  limitation  of,  on  com- 
petition, 579 ;  economic  effects  of,  706 

Arbitration,  Part  II.  ch.  iii.  p.  222 ; 
out  of  place  in  questions  of  interpre- 
tation, 183  ;  character  of,  222  ;  scope 
of  term,  223  ;  assumptions  of,  230  ; 
in  iron  trade,  231,  234;  in  coal- 
mining, 234  ;  compulsory,  244  ;  in 
Victorian  and  New  Zealand  law,  246; 
ii.  814  ;  operatives  object  to,  228 ; 
employers  object  to,  227  ;  on  restric- 
tion of  boy-labor,  ii.  484 ;  in  de- 
marcation disputes,  521,  522 ;  in 
railway  service,  776 ;  future  scope 
for,  814.  See  Joint  Committees  and 
Boards 

Argyll,  Duke  of,  ii.  868 

Arlidge,  Dr.  J.  T.,  358 

Armstrong's  Engineering  Works  (Els- 
wick),  104,  130 ;  ii.  457,  777 

Artel,  the,  ii.  808 

Artificial  changes,  character  of,  ii.  560 

Ashley,  Professor  W.  J. ,  5 

Ashton,  Thomas,  secretary  Oldham 
Cotton-spinners,  199,  201 

Asking  ticket,  438 

Assessmentism,  vice  of,  156 

Association  of  Producers,  402  ;  ii.  811  ; 
of  employers  and  employed  to  restrict 
output,  ii.  577 

Assumptions  of  arbitrators,  230 ;  of 
Trade  Unionism,  vol.  ii.  Part.  II.  ch. 
xiii.  pp.  559-599 

Atlantic  liner,  ii.  509,  761 

Austin,  John,  ii.  845 

Australian  coal,  ii.  741  ;  wool,  742 

Austria,  accident  insurance  in,  382, 
385 »  39O ;  small  master  system  in, 
414 

Autocracy,  relation  of  Trade  Unionism 
to,  ii.  807 

Ayrshire  Coalminers,  447 

BABBAGE,  C.,  318;  ii.  724,  726 
Baernreither,  Dr.  J.,  89 
Bagman,  spirit  of  the,  ii.  581 


Bain,  E.,  336 

Bakers,  an  Irish  national  union  of,  87  ; 
Trade  Union  membership  among, 
287  ;  insist  on  time  work,  287  ;  not 
to  work  in  any  newly-opened  under- 
ground bakehouse,  360  ;  support  of, 
by  public  opinion,  ii.  535 

Balfour,  Rt.  Hon.  Arthur,  ii.  538 
—  Kt.  Hon.  Gerald,  ii.  536 

Ball,  John,  394 

Ballot,  not  used  by  early  trade  clubs, 
7 ;  among  Northumberland  Coal- 
miners,  34  ;  required  before  a  strike, 
41,  62  ;  among  engineers,  also  before 
closing  strike,  96 ;  suggested  for 
"contracting  out,"  373 

Banfield,  T.  C,  ii.  618 

Bankruptcy,  liability  to,  under  Direct 
Legislation,  23  ;  as  result  of  rivalry 
between  unions,  113;  under  stress 
of  bad  trade  or  a  prolonged  strike, 
155 ;  difficulty  of  employers',  in 
accident  cases,  389 

Barge-builders,  ii.  509 

Barnes,  George,  133  ;  ii.  524,  823 

Basketmakers,  piecework  lists  of,  283  ; 
apprenticeship  among,  ii.  462  ;  pro- 
tection of  employers  by,  579 

Basle,  municipal  insurance  against  un- 
employment at,  1 60 

Bastable,  Professor  C.  F.,  ii.  864 

Batley,  ii.  672 

Beach,  ii.  510 

Rt.   Hon.  Sir  Michael  Hicks-,  ii. 

534 

Beamers,  wages  of,  105  ;  type  of  Trade 
Unionism  required  by,  106 ;  federal 
relations  of,  258  ;  strategic  position 
of,  ii.  478  ;  exclusion  of  women  by, 
498.  See  also  Cotton  Operatives 

Becher,  Rev.  J.  T.,  14 

Bedstead    manufacture,    ii.    578,     741, 

747     • 

Beehive,  the,  338  ;  ii.  587,  588 

Beesly,  Professor  E.  S.,  157,  159,  160 ; 
"'•  587,  853 

Belfast,  growth  of  Trade  Unionism  in, 
87  ;  overlap  in,  ii.  518;  Engineers,  96 

Bell  horses,  305 

Benefits,  evil  of  confusing  friendly  and 
dispute,  94  ;  successful  administration 
of,  by  Boilermakers,  99 ;  need  for 
jury  system,  loo ;  variety  of,  105, 
152;  proposals  to  raise,  112,  116; 
rivalry  in  amount  of,  113,  115; 
practice  of  new  unions  with  regard 
to,  153;  insecurity  of,  154,  159; 


Index 


903 


actuarial  criticism  of,  155  ;  use  of,  in 
Trade  Unionism,  158  ;  fundamental 
purpose  of,  161  ;  adjustment  of,  for 
members  taken  over,  ii.  526  ;  objec- 
tion to  any  State  competition  with, 
529  ;  lying-in,  638,  642  ;  future  of, 
826 

Bentham,  Jeremy,  ii.  567 

Bernard,  T.  N.,  ii.  611 

Berne,  municipal  insurance  against  un- 
employment at,  1 60 

Bertram,  Anton,  246  ;  ii.  815 

Besant,  Annie,  ii.  638 

Bibliography,  ii.  878-900 

Bimetallism  at  Trade  Union  Congress, 
271 

Birmingham,  alliances  at,  ii.  577,  665, 
806;  Bedstead  Makers,  578;  Flint 
Glass  Makers,  802 ;  Pearl  Button- 
makers,  395  ;  ii.  463,  498 ;  Wire- 
weavers,  564 

Birmingham  Daily  Post,  the,  ii.  578 

Birrell,  Augustine,  366 

Birth-rate,  ii.  636-643  ;  in  England  for 
past  thirty  years,  639 ;  in  France, 
636.  See  Appendix  III. 

Birtwistle,  Thomas,  196,  310 

Blackburn  Beamers,  Twisters,  and 
Drawers,  ii.  499 

Blacklegging  by  rival  Trade  Unions, 
120 ;  by  women,  ii.  497,  499,  505 

Blackstone,  ii.  477 

Bladesmiths,  ii.  480 

Blanc,  Louis,  ii.  570 

Blatchford,  R.  P.,  36 

Bleachers,  sick  pay  of,  161 

Blochairn  Works,  ii.  494 

Blockmakers,  ii.  509 

Blockprinters,  ii.  460,  462 

Board  of  Trade  (including  Labor  De- 
partment and  Labour  Gazette),  105, 
156,  175,  186,  187,  192,  203,  209, 
243,  256,  283,  285,  286,  332,  373, 
398,  408  ;  ii.  495,  499,  544,  584,  594, 
777,  798,  811 

Boat-builders,  ii.  509 

Bodiker,  Dr.  T.,  366 

Bohm-Bawerk,  E.  von,  ii.  648,  673 

Boilermakers,  palatial  offices  of,  at 
Newcastle,  17  ;  mode  of  electing 
executive,  18;  description  of  union  of, 
28,  99  ;  change  of  constitution  of,  31, 
49  ;  foreign  branches  of,  8 1  ;  at- 
tempted Scottish  secession  from,  82  ; 
national  agreements  of,  97  ;  clear 
distinction  between  friendly  and  dis- 
pute benefits  among,  99 ;  type  of 


Trade  Unionism  desired  by,  108, 
171  ;  proposed  inclusion  of,  with 
engineers,  no;  wealth  of,  108,  117  ; 
inclusion  of  holders-up  among,  1 28  ; 
in  federal  union  with  other  trades, 
132;  collective  agreements  of,  176; 
machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining 
among,  204 ;  object  to  arbitration, 
228 ;  system  of  fines  among,  208  ; 
refuse  to  work  with  non-unionists, 
215  ;  desire  certificates  of  efficiency, 
252 ;  disinclination  for  legislation, 
255j  263  ;  work  either  piece  or  time, 
287,  291,  300;  Trade  Union  mem- 
bership of,  287  ;  relations  to  helpers, 
291,  296  ;  by-laws  of,  300  ;  indiffer- 
ence of,  to  Normal  Days,  342  ;  re- 
quire certificate  of  safety  of  oil  tanks, 
358  ;  encourage  machinery  by  allow- 
ances, 410 ;  regulation  of  apprentice- 
ship by,  ii.  456,  463,  470,  480 ;  cases 
of  overlap  of,  509 ;  demarcation 
agreements  of,  520  ;  position  of,  in 
Federation  of  Engineering 'Trades, 
523  ;  rely  mainly  on  Collective  Bar- 
gaining, 562  ;  extreme  fluctuations 
in  earnings  of,  583  ;  high  wages  of, 

593 

Bologna,  insurance  against  unemploy- 
ment at,  160 

Bolton,  concentration  of  cotton  trade 
round  about,  258 ;  Bleachers  and 
Dyers,  161  ;  Cotton-spinners,  41,  92, 
125,  312;  ii.  729;  Ironfounders,  72, 
145  ;  Stonemasons,  305 

Bonus,  system  of,  297  ;  ii.  551,  552 

Bookbinders,  declare  rules  unalterable, 
25  ;  obtain  eight  hours'  day  in  Lon- 
don, 131,  352  ;  need  for  federal  rela- 
tions with  compositors,  131  ;  work 
either  piece  or  time,  287  ;  Trade 
Union  membership  of,  287  ;  hours  of 
labor  of,  336,  352 ;  ancient  drinking 
habits  of,  327 

Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives,  branches 
governed  by  tumultuous  mass  meet- 
ings, 10 ;  constitution  of  union  of, 
47 »  5°  5  object  to  work  being  sent 
into  the  country,  78  ;  national  agree- 
ments of,  97,  185-192  ;  declared  ob- 
jects of,  147,  252  ;  joint  committees 
and  local  boards  of,  185-192  ;  non- 
unionists  among,  209  ;  political  ob- 
jects of,  252  ;  insist  on  piecework, 
286,  398  ;  Trade  Union  membership 
of,  286  ;  serious  friction  among,  over 
machinery  and  the  team  system,  396- 


904 


Index 


406  ;  strike  against  sewing-machine, 
393  ;  claim  whole  value  of  product, 
402  ;  different  classes  of,  418  ;  evolu- 
tion of,  from  hand  shoemakers,  418  ; 
earnings  of,  400,  406  ;  employment 
of  boys  among,  400  ;  policy  of,  in 
times  of  depression,  443  ;  attempt  to 
limit  boy-labor,  ii.  483-487  ;  compul- 
sory character  of  collective  agreements 
of,  533  ;  objection  of,  to  home  work, 
540 ;  to  small  masters,  548  ;  effect  of 
Common  Rules  of,  549,  727.  See 
also  Shoemakers 

Booth,  Charles,  xiv,  433,  434  ;  ii.  529, 
557,  589,  642,  722,  750,  757,  766,  827 

Borgeaud,  C.,  19 

Boroughs,  disfranchisement  of,  ii.  569 

Bounty,  ii.  749-760,  767 

Bo  wen,  Francis,  ii.  618 

Box-club  of  Woolcombers,  162 

Boycott  of  non-unionists,  29,  73,  75,  78, 
80,  86,  121,  207,  213,  215,  407  ;  ii. 
458,  467,  475,  481,  483,  489,  508, 

5i9»  533,  562,  707 

Boy  -  labor,  uneconomic  nature  of, 
400  ;  attempt  to  restrict,  ii.  482-489  ; 
Lord  James's  award  as  to,  485  ;  con- 
nection of  limitation  of,  with  Doctrine 
of  Supply  and  Demand,  573  ;  econo- 
mic effect  of  limiting,  704-715,  768  ; 
relation  of  educational  reforms  to, 
769;  future  of,  8n 

Boyle,  Sir  Courtenay,  209,  241 

Brabrook,  E.  M.,  Chief  Registrar  of 
Friendly  Societies,  159,  388 

Bradford  dyers,  287 ;  builders'  laborers, 
304  ;  Stuff-pressers,  ii.  463  ;  Packing- 
case  Makers,  ii.  486 

Brad  laugh,  Charles,  ii.  638 

Braelers,  ii.  498 

Branch  governed  by  general  meeting, 
10,  40 ;  institution  of  governing 
branch,  12,  17  ;  method  of  voting 
among  the  Northumberland  coal- 
miners,  34  ;  number  of  branches  in 
foreign  countries,  81  ;  in  Ireland, 
87  ;  character  of  Irish  branches,  84  ; 
character  of  Scottish  branches,  83  ; 
decay  of  branch  autonomy,  88-103  J 
character  of  branch  meetings,  90 ; 
independence  of  branches  among  the 
engineers,  94  ;  function  of  the  branch 
as  jury  and  unit  of  representative 
government,  100 ;  federal  relations 
between  branches  in  building  trades  ; 
128 ;  use  of,  for  Collective  Bargain- 
ing* 179;  future  of,  ii.  834 


Brass-workers,  108,  in,  118,  134,287; 

ii.  486,  509.     See  also  Engineers 
Brazil,  slavery  in,  ii.  75  * 
Brentano,  Dr.  Luigi,  247,  324,  347 ;  ii. 

454,  565 

Bribery,  prevalence  of,  ii.  674 

Brick  cutting,  284 

Bricklayers,  declare  rules  unalterable, 
25  ;  separate  organisation  of  Scotch 
and  English,  83  ;  spasmodic  local 
strikes  of,  98  ;  persistence  of  local 
autonomy  among,  98  ;  federal  rela- 
tions of,  127,  134 ;  accusations  of 
blacklegging  among,  120  ;  working 
rules  of,  175  ;  machinery  for  Collec- 
tive Bargaining  among,  180  ;  Trade 
Union  membership  of,  287  ;  differen- 
tiation of  work  among,  283  ;  object 
to  piecework,  287,  298  ;  attempt  to 
limit  speed  of  working,  304 ;  hours 
of  labor  of,  340,  352 ;  insist  on 
place  for  meals,  360 ;  in  London, 
recruited  from  laborers,  ii.  489  ; 
ancient  gild  of,  480  ;  demarcation 
disputes  of,  515  ;  prefer  large  em- 
ployers, 549  ;  baffled  by  the  jerry- 
builder,  549 

Bright,  John,  308  ;  ii.  868 

Briquet,  C.  M.,  ii.  708 

Bristol  Boot  Trade  Board,  187,  209 

Britannia  Metal  Smiths,  ii.  458,  459 

British  Library  of  Political  Science,  175 

Broadhurst,  Henry,  370,  385  ;  ii.  529 

Brooklands  Agreement,  203 

Brown,  Edmond,  366 

Browne,  Sir  Benjamin,  ii.  732 

Bruce,  A.  B.,  296 

Brushmakers,  order  at  meetings  of,  4  ; 
amount  of  drink  allowed,  5  ;  con- 
stitutional form  of  union  of,  13 ; 
method  of  voting  among,  14  ;  piece- 
work lists  of,  283  ;  indifference  of,  to 
Normal  Day,  343  ;  objected  to  ma- 
chinery, 394  ;  apprenticeship  among, 
ii.  462  ;  exclusion  of  women  from, 
502 

Brussels,  minimum  wage  at,  ii.  776 

Bryce,  Rt.  Hon.  James,  19,  68 

Buckle,  II.  T.,  ii.  566 

ftuilde?-,  the,  ii.  515 

Builders'  laborers,  working  rules  of, 
!75>  3°4  :  attempt  to  limit  speed  of 
working,  304  ;  insist  on  payment  for 
overtime,  340 ;  progress  to  be  brick- 
layers, ii.  489 

—  Union  of   1833-34,  constitutional 
form   of,    12  ;    unique    character  of, 


Index 


905 


127  ;  desired  to  prohibit  overtime, 
340 

Building  regulations,  ii.  734 

trades,  survival  of  local  auto- 
nomy in,  97  ;  friction  between  dif- 
ferent branches  of,  98,  120  ;  attempt 
at  national  amalgamation  of,  109, 
127  ;  federal  relations  of,  127,  134  ; 
local  Building  Trades  Councils, 
127  ;  working  rules  of,  175,  304, 
360 ;  strike  of,  in  1859-60,  largely 
non-unionist,  178  ;  object  to  piece- 
work, 287,  297  ;  chasing  in,  305  ; 
Trade  Union  membership  of,  287  ; 
desire  for  Normal  Day  in,  339  ;  over- 
time in,  340,  347  ;  hours  of  labor 
of,  340,  352  ;  decay  of  apprentice- 
ship in,  ii.  489  ;  absence  of  demar- 
cation disputes  in,  510;  preference 
of,  for  large  employers,  549 

Bureaucracy,  beginning  of,  15  ;  primi- 
tive democracy  results  in,  26,  36, 
59  ;  among  the  Boilermakers,  30 ; 
controlled  by  Representative  Assem- 
bly, 43,  59  ;  only  partially  controlled 
by  Representative  Executive,  51 

Burial,  expenses  of,  152,  154,  170;  ii. 
529,  75°,  797,  827 

Burnett,  John,  156,  160,  340;   ii.  544 

Burnley  Cotton-weavers,  289 

Burns,  John,  76,  133 

Burt,  Thomas,  262;  ii.  511,  512,  513 

Burton,  John  Hill,  416,  447 

Bury  tapesizers,  165 

Butcher,  406 

Butty  master  system,  290,  298,  318 

CABINET,  government  by,  in  the  Trade 
Union  world,  30-46  ;  among  the 
Boilermakers,  30  ;  among  the  Cotton- 
spinners,  39  ;  among  the  Coalminers, 
43  ;  election  of,  by  districts,  47  ;  of 
the  Trade  Union  Congress,  265-278 

Cabinetmakers,  shop  bargain  among, 
173  ;  work  either  piece  or  time,  287, 
301;  Trade  Union  membership  among, 
287  ;  disuse  of  piecework  lists  of, 
301  ;  degeneration  of  unorganised 
sections  of,  416;  demarcation  dis- 
putes of,  ii.  509,  517,  516  ;  sweating 
among  the,  543 

Cadbury's  cocoa,  ii.  683,  690 

Cairnes,  John  Elliot,  ii.  605,  611,  614, 
6 1 6,  630,  653 

Calico  printers,  ii.  462,  481,  768 

Campbell,  G.  L.,  366 

Cannan,  Edwin,  ii.  604,  616,  618,  624 


Capital,  causes  influencing  accumula- 
tion of,  ii.  610-632  ;  rate  of  interest 
on,  611,  625,  627  ;  flow  of,  629  ;  dis- 
tribution of,  among  trades,  740-749 

Capital  and  Labour,  227 

Cardiff,  trade  agreements  at,  ii.  520  ; 
export  trade  of,  741  ;  Engineers,  358  ; 
ii.  520 

Cardroom  operatives,  wages  of,  105  ; 
type  of  Trade  Unionism  required  by, 
106 ;  relation  of,  to  spinners,  123, 
128 ;  federal  relations  of,  124,  258  ; 
work  either  piece  or  time,  287  ; 
Trade  Union  membership  of,  287  ; 
support  Cotton-spinners,  323  ;  admit 
ring-spinners  to  membership,  424. 
See  also  Cotton  Operatives 

Carey,  H.  C,  ii.  866 

Carmen,  political  objects  of,  252  ;  ex- 
cluded from  Workmen's  Compensa- 
tion Act,  389  ;  long  hours  of,  ii.  800 

Carpenters,  expenditure  on  drink,  of 
Preston,  5 ;  formation  of  General  Union 
of,  12  ;  mode  of  electing  executive 
among,  17 ;  delegate  meetings  of, 
19  ;  declare  rules  unalterable,  25  ; 
absorption  of  local  societies  of,  73, 
76 ;  wide  dispersion  of,  53,  8 1  ; 
foreign  branches  of,  81  ;  separate 
organisation  of  Scotch  and  English, 
83  ;  Irish  branches  of,  86,  87  ;  cen- 
tralisation among,  91  ;  relations  be- 
tween the  two  great  unions  of,  122  ; 
divergence  of  interest  between  Ship- 
wrights and,  130 ;  federal  relations 
of,  with  other  trades,  132,  134  ;  as- 
serted bankruptcy  of,  156  ;  working 
rules  of,  175  ;  hours  of  labor  of, 
255,  340,  352  ;  insist  on  time  work, 
287,  297  ;  differentiation  of  work 
among,  284  ;  diversity  of  local 
wages  of,  321  ;  desire  of,  for  Normal 
Day,  340,  352  ;  object  to  overtime, 
340  ;  London  gild  of,  ii.  480,  510  ; 
demarcation  disputes  of,  509-519  ; 
position  of,  in  Federation  of  Engineer- 
ing Trades,  523 

Carpet- weavers,  286  ;    ii.  481,  486 

Casting  vote,  193,  223.  See  also  Arbi- 
tration^ Umpire 

Casual  labor,  effect  of,  433  ;  ii.  545, 
7i8,  755.  757,  791 

Caucus,  use  of,  among  the  cotton- 
spinners,  41 

Caulkers,  ii.  509 

Cemeteries,  vested  interests  of,  un- 
protected, ii.  569 


906 


Index 


Certificate,  proposed  requirement  of, 
252  ;  ii.  495  ;  of  safety  in  oil  ships, 
358 ;  desired  by  Enginemen  and 
Plumbers,  ii.  495 

Chain  and  nail  workers,  365,  416;  ii. 

543,  544,  583,  754,  757 
Chamberlain,    Rt.   Hon.  J.,  230,   366, 

387,  388,  390 ;  ii.  538 

Chance's  glassworks,  375 

Chapel,  printers',  299 

Chapman,  Maria  Weston,  ii.  608,  752 

Character,  effect  of  Restriction  of 
Numbers  on,  ii.  705  ;  effect  of  the 
Common  Rule  on,  ii.  716 

Charity,  effect  of,  ii.  718,  756 

Chartered  companies,  ii.  680 

Chateauneuf,  Benoison  de,  ii.  637 

Checkweigher,  often  Trade  Union 
official,  16,  44,  212  ;  ballot  and  com- 
pulsory payment  for,  212  ;  ii.  828  ; 
agitation  for  provision  of,  309 

Cheshire  Coalminers,  45 

Chester,  picketing  at,  ii.  855 

Child,  Sir  Josiah,  ii.  622,623,  626,  871 

Children's  employment.  See  also  Boy- 
labor 

Chippers  and  Drillers,  imperfect 
organisation  of,  81  ;  demarcation 
disputes  of,  ii.  509 

Christian  Socialists,  the,  ii.  603,  618 

Cigar  makers,  286 

Civil  Service  Supply  Association,  ii. 
669 

Clare,  George,  ii.  870 

Clarion,  the,  36 

Clere,  Jules,  26 

Cleveland  ironminers,  229 ;  work  by 
the  piece,  286;  Trade  Union  member- 
ship of,  286 

Clickers.  See  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives 
and  Compositors 

Clicking,  among  Compositors,  299 

Climbing  boys,  abolition  of,  363 

Cloggers,  430 

Cloth  manufacture,  prevalence  of  out- 
work in,  ii.  543 

Clothing  manufacture,  inadequacy  of 
factory  legislation  as  to,  364 ; 
irregularity  of  employment  in,  433  ; 
sweating  in,  ii.  543,  763 

Clyde.     See  Glasgow 

Coachmakers,  delegate  meetings  of,  19 ; 
adopt  Referendum,  21  ;  gradually 
restrict  its  use,  23  ;  insist  on  time 
work,  287  ;  Trade  Union  member- 
ship among,  287  ;  object  to  engage- 
ment, 432  ;  forbid  smooting,  439 


Coal,  international  trade  in,  ii.  741 

Coalminers,  election  of  officers  from 
among  checkweigh-men,  16 ;  Nor- 
thumberland and  Durham,  survival 
of  Direct  Legislation  among,  32 ; 
effect  of  Imperative  Mandate  among, 
33  ;  method  of  voting  among,  34,  45  ; 
adoption  of  representative  institutions 
by,  38,  43 ;  character  of  the  represent- 
ative among,  54  5  federal  relations 
among,  125  ;  divergence  of  sectional 
interests  among,  126  ;  small  use  of 
friendly  benefits  among,  171  ;  refusal 
of,  to  work  with  non-unionists,  214  ; 
demand  for  Mines  Regulation  Acts, 
250,  261 ;  hours  of  labor  among, 
255  ;  political  machinery  of,  260 ; 
political  activity  of,  260  ;  difficulties 
of,  in  Parliament,  262  ;  influence  of, 
in  Trade  Union  Congress,  278  ; 
insist  on  piecework,  286,  290 ; 
Trade  Union  membership  among, 
286  ;  checkweighing  of,  309  : 
desire  of,  for  Normal  Day,  339 ; 
desire  precautions  against  accidents, 
355,  368,  374,  382 ;  attitude  of,  to 
contracting  out,  372,  374;  policy  of 
restricting  output,  446-450 ;  impose 
no  restriction  on  entrance  to  trade, 
ii.  474  ;  prohibition  of  women  work- 
ing as,  496 ;  absence  of  friendly 
benefits  among,  529 »  compulsory 
character  of  collective  agreements  of, 
533  ;  demand  of,  for  Living  Wage, 
589 ;  use  of  Sliding  Scale  among,  576. 
See  also  Miners'1  Federation 

Cobbett,  W.,  171 

Cobblers,  demarcation  with  Cord- 
wainers,  ii.  510 

Cobden,  Richard,  ii.  868 

Coffins,  ii.  510 

Cohn,  Professor  Gustav,  ii.  585 

Cokemen,  35,  125,  126.  See  also  Coal- 
miners 

Colchester  Engineers,  346 

Collective  Bargaining,  origin  of  term,  1 73 ; 
description  of,  173-177;  machinery 
for,  179;  incidental  compulsion  of, 
206 ;  extent  of,  178 ;  inclusion  of 
non-unionists  in,  209  ;  predominance 
of,  between  1824  and  1885,  249 ; 
need  of,  with  regard  to  hours  of 
labor,  327,  333  ;  required  for  Sanita- 
tion and  Safety,  354,  386 ;  must  be 
admitted  with  regard  to  new  processes 
and  machinery,  404,  411  ;  not  com- 
pletely legalised  until  1871,  411  ;  use 


Index 


907 


of,  for  sharing  work,  440,  442 ; 
inconsistent  with  annual  engagement, 
432 ;  with  regard  to  apprenticeship, 
ii.  456-472  ;  strengthened  by  group 
system,  478  ;  with  regard  to  boy- 
labor,  483-488 ;  with  regard  to  pro- 
gression, 490  ;  with  regard  to  women's 
labor,  500-507  ;  with  regard  to  demar- 
cation disputes,  520 ;  proposed  legal 
enforcement  of,  534  J  by  alliances  of 
masters  and  men,  577  ;  future  of,  804, 

8i3 
Collectivism,    in   Trade    Unionism,   ii. 

598  ;  future  of,  807-850 
Collet,  Clara,  105  ;  ii.  495 
Colliery  mechanics,  36,  125,  126 
Cologne,   insurance  against  unemploy- 
ment at,  1 60 

Combination,    economic  demonstration 
of  necessity  for,  ii.  649,  701 

Laws,  economic  effect  of,  ii.  608 

Committee.      See   Cabinet;    Executive 

Committee 

Common    employment,   366-370,    385, 
388;   ii.  522 

Lodging  Houses,  ii.  734 

Rule,  Device  of  the,  ii.  560 

Communism,  time  wages  described  as, 
282;    British    workmen    not  sympa- 
thetic to,   282,   323 ;   suggestion  of, 
as  regards  Normal  Day,  353 
Compensation    desired    for    accidents, 
271,  365-376  ;  effect  of  1897  Act  for, 
387 ;  practice  with  regard  to,  ii.  566 
Competition,   analysis   of  effect  of,  ii. 
654-702 

between  trades,  ii.  740-749 

between     Trade      Unions,    112; 

leading    to     "blacklegging,"     120 ; 
rendering  federation  necessary,  112- 
141 ;  resulting  in  demarcation  disputes, 
ii.  508-527 
Competitive  examination  for  offices,  16, 

196  ;  specimen  papers  of,  197 
Compositors,  Manchester,  allowed 
smoking,  5 ;  Glasgow,  election 
customs,  6 ;  London,  governed  by 
general  meeting,  10 ;  adopt  Refer- 
endum from  continental  democrats, 
21;  electioneering  policy  of,  80 ; 
separate  organisation  of  Scotch  and 
English,  83 ;  irregularities  of  Irish 
branches  of,  85,  87  ;  employ  salaried 
organiser  for  Ireland,  87 ;  Trade 
Union  membership  among,  287 ; 
work  either  time  or  piece,  287,  298  ; 
introduction  of  stab  among,  299 ; 


clicking  system  of,  299 ;  drinking 
habits  of,  327 ;  indifference  of,  to 
Normal  Day,  342  ;  object  to  compos- 
ing machines,  407  ;  now  work  the 
Linotype  under  collective  agreement, 
407 ;  news  men  guaranteed  a  mini- 
mum earning,  408,  436  ;  policy  of, 
with  regard  to  apprenticeship,  ii. 
464-468  ;  with  regard  to  women,  499- 
507  ;  wages  of  women  as,  499  ;  seek 
to  increase  mobility,  731  ;  proposed 
trade  classes  for  unemployed,  830 
Compulsory  service  in  Trade  Union 
offices,  5-7  ;  acceptance  of  sliding 
scale,  209 ;  membership  of  joint 
committees,  211  ;  obedience  to  Trade 
Union  rules,  207 ;  deduction  of 
weekly  contribution,  209,  211  ;  pay- 
ment for  checkweigher,  212;  member- 
ship of  Trade  Union,  213  ;  Collective 
Bargaining,  218  ;  precautions  against 
accident,  361,  377  ;  insurance 
premiums  strongly  objected  to,  385  ; 
ii.  529 ;  character  of  Collective 
Bargaining,  534 ;  trade  classes  for, 
830 

Comte,  Auguste,  ii.  845 
Concentration  of  business,  ii.  727 
Conciliation,  distinguished  from  arbitra- 
tion, 223,  239  ;  out  of  place  in  ques- 
tions of  interpretation,  183;  not  then 
required    in    organised    trade,    236 ; 
recent  cases  of,  225,  241  ;  real  sphere 
of,    238 ;   working   of  English   Act, 
244.     See  Z\S,Q  Joint  Committees  and 
Boards 

Condy's  Fluid,  ii.  685 
Connecticut,  early  use  of  Referendum 
in,   19;  boot  factories  of,  400,  413; 
ii.  727 

Conseils  de  prud'hommes,  226 
Conservativism,  in  Trade  Unionism,  ii. 

597 

Considerant,  Victor,  21 

Consumer,  pressure  of  the,  ii.  671 

Consumption,  influence  of,  ii.  671,  740, 
746 

Contingent  fund,  95 

Continuity  of  employment,  vol.  i.  Part 
II.  ch.  ix.  pp.  430-453 

of  livelihood,  an  object  of  Trade 

Unionism,  146,  430 ;  an  object  of 
accident  compensation,  371,  378, 
379 ;  not  secured  by  lowering  rates 
in  competition  with  machine,  415; 
nor  yet  by  annual  hirings,  431  ;  in- 
fluence of  desire  for,  on  demarcation 


908 


Index 


disputes,  ii.  515,  516.  See  also  Con- 
tinuity of  Employment 

Contracting  out,  370-386 

Contributions,  collected  by  paid  officers 
among  Cotton- weavers  and  Card-room 
operatives,  106  ;  proposals  to  lower, 

112,  Il6;    rivalry   in   smallness   of, 

113,  115;    objection  to  any  rivalry 
in  collecting,   373,   385  ;  adjustment 
of,  on  transfer  of  members,  ii.  526 

Co-operative  contract  system,  295 

movement,  the,  88,  268,  406  ;  ii. 

693,  810,  811,  818,  819,  824 

Coopers,  local  monopoly  among,  74 ; 
peculiar  rules  of  the  Dublin,  75,  213  ; 
looseness  of  national  organisation 
among,  91  ;  imperfect  machinery  for 
Collective  Bargaining  among,  179 ; 
taxation  without  representation  among 
Dublin,  213  ;  Trade  Union  member- 
ship among,  287  ;  work  either  time 
or  piece,  287,  336 ;  old  piecework 
lists  of,  283  ;  hours  of  labor  of,  336, 
341  ;  desire  of,  for  Normal  Day,  342  ; 
objected  to  machinery,  394 ;  patri- 
mony among,  ii.  460 ;  limitation  of 
apprenticeship  among,  462  ;  vested 
interest  of,  in  the  liquor  traffic,  564 

Copartnership,  ii.  811 

Coppersmiths,  108,  in,  118,  134;  ii. 
486,  509,  564.  See  also  Engineers 

Copyright,  analogy  of,  ii.  567 

Cordwainers.     See  Shoemakers 

Cork  Stonemasons,  75 

Cornwall,  Stonemasons  in,  ii.  461 

Cotton  Factory  Times,  203,  315,  339, 
427,  729,  857 

Cotton  manufacture,  grades  of  workers 
and  wages  in,  105  ;  geographical 
specialisation  of,  125  ;  concentration 
of,  about  Bolton,  258  ;  absolute  pro- 
hibition of  overtime  in,  348  ;  extreme 
regulation  of,  348,  364  ;  progress  of 
machinery  in,  413  ;  policy  in,  with 
regard  to  gluts,  449  ;  sexual  morality 
in  the,  ii.  497  ;  causes  of  progress  of, 
725  ;  concentration  of  business  in, 
729  ;  foreign  competition  with,  743  ; 
early  child  labor  in,  752  ;  state  of, 
867 

operatives,  appointment  of  officers 

of,  by  competitive  examination,  16, 
196  ;  adoption  of  representative  in- 
stitutions by,  38 ;  character  of  the 
representative  among,  54  ;  classes  of, 
and  their  wages,  105  ;  federal  rela- 
tions among,  123,  258;  small  use  of 


friendly  benefits  among,  171  ;  national 
agreements  of,  176  ;  object  to  arbitra- 
tion, 228  ;  machinery  for  interpreta- 
tion disputes,  195,  236  ;  machinery 
for  Collective  Bargaining  among,  195- 
204 ;  Trade  Union  membership 
among,  286 ;  insist  on  piecework, 
286,  288  ;  particulars  clause  among, 
310  ;  diary  of  official  of,  312  ;  object 
to  deductions,  314 ;  desire  of,  for 
Normal  Day,  338,  440 ;  increasing 
stringency  of  factory  legislation  for, 
348,  364  ;  support  sanitary  legislation, 
364 ;  cordially  encourage  improve- 
ments, 409  ;  penalise  backward  em- 
ployers, 413  ;  absence  of  restrictions 
on  entrance  to  the  trade,  ii.  474  ; 
absence  of  demarcation  disputes 
among,  510 

Cotton-spinners,  drinking  rules  of,  5  ; 
permanence  of  tenure  of  secretaryship 
among,  17  ;  constitution  of  union 
of,  38 ;  abandon  federation  for  a 
centralised  amalgamation  in  each 
province,  92,  124;  national  agree- 
ments of,  97  ;  wages  of,  105  ;  ii.  474 ; 
type  of  Trade  Unionism  required  by, 
106  ;  federal  relations  of,  123,  258  ; 
technical  specialisation  of,  125  ;  de- 
clared objects  of,  146 ;  collective 
agreements  of,  176  ;  fluctuations  of 
wages  among,  256  ;  manifesto  upon 
Nine  Hours'  Bill,  250 ;  political  action 
of,  259 ;  insist  on  piecework,  286, 
288  ;  Trade  Union  membership  of, 
286  ;  desire  of,  for  Normal  Day,  327, 
338  ;  encourage  improvements,  409  ; 
penalise  backward  employers,  413  ; 
do  not  resist  women  ring-spinners, 
424 ;  suggest  short  time  instead 
of  reduction,  449 ;  hours  of  labor 
of,  440  ;  absence  of  apprenticeship 
restrictions  among,  ii.  475  ;  system 
of  joining  or  partnering  among,  475  ; 
relation  of,  to  piecers,  475,  494,  497  ; 
leave  selection  to  employer,  494  ; 
compulsory  character  of  Collective 
Bargaining  of,  533  ;  intensity  of 
application  of,  592  ;  disuse  of  picket- 
ing among,  719.  See  also  Col  fan 
Operatives  and  Cotton-iveavers 

spinners'  Parliament,  the,  descrip- 
tion of,  41  ;  composition  of,  57 

thread,  prices  and  wages  in,  445 

—  -weavers  promote  uniformity  of 
rates,  79 ;  wages  of,  105  ;  type  of 
Trade  Unionism  required  by,  106  ; 


Index 


909 


employ  collectors,  106  ;  federal  rela- 
tions of,  124,  258;  adopt  uniform 
list,  79>  I25  >  tendency  to  centralisa- 
tion, 125  ;  political  action  of,  259  ; 
object  to  over-steaming,  272,  358, 
364  ;  insist  on  piecework,  286  ; 
Trade  Union  membership  among, 
286;  object  to  deductions,  315  ; 
desire  of,  for  Normal  Day,  338  ;  en- 
courage improvements  in  machinery, 
409  ;  suggest  short  time  instead  of 
reduction,  449  ;  sexual  morality  of, 
ii.  497  ;  have  always  admitted  women 
to  membership,  500  ;  sex  segregation 
by  piecework  rates,  501,  504,  507  ; 
seek  to  increase  mobility,  ii.  731. 
See  also  Cotton  Operatives 

County  average,  183,  192,  193,  311  ;  ii. 
728 

Court  leet,  ii.  458 

Courtney,     Rt.     Hon.    Leonard,    218, 

219  5  "•  534 

Coventry  ribbon  trade,  401 

Cox,  Harold,  324,  441  ;  ii.  565 

Crawford,  William,  215 

Cree,  T.  S.,  ii.  611,  612,  656 

Creeler,  ii.  481 

Cripps,  C.A.,  ii.  567 

Crompton,  Henry,  205,  223 

Crusoe,  Robinson,  ii.  846 

Cumberland  Coalminers,  45  ;  Iron- 
workers, 235 

Cunningham,  Rev.  W.,  448;  ii.  454 

Curran  v.  Treleaven,  ii.  854 

Curriers,  curious  rotation  of  office 
among,  7  ;  remarkable  use  of  Mutual 
Insurance  among,  170;  insist  on 
piecework,  286  ;  Trade  Union  mem- 
bership among,  286 

Custom,  as  affecting  standard  earnings, 
ii.  695 

Cutlers.     See  Sheffield  trades 

Daily  Chronicle,  the,  366 ;  ii.  555 

Daire,  E.,  ii.  570 

Dairies,  municipal,  ii.  788 

Dale,  Sir  David,  232;  ii.  534 

Dallinger,  F.  W.,  42 

Darg,  446 

Darlington  Carpenters,  53 ;  Pattern- 
makers, 119 

Darwin,  Charles,  ii.  637 

Datal   hands,   desire   piecework,    290 ; 
insist  on  Normal  Day,  331,  336,  340  ;    j 
tendency  of  employers  to  revert  to, 
400,  401 

Davis,  W.  J.,  ii.  578 


Deductions,  Boot  operatives  object  to, 
147 ;  ii.  540  ;  Cotton  operatives  object 
to,  314,  317  ;  for  spoiled  work  ob- 
jected to,  315  ;  Potters  object  to, 
316  ;  Glass  Bottle  Makers  object  to, 
316 ;  Ironfounders  object  to,  316 ; 
Coalminers  object  to,  317  ;  for  em- 
ployers' benefit  society  objected  to, 
373  >  ii-  55°  5  f°r  compulsory  insur- 
ance objected  to,  272,  385  ;  ii.  529  ; 
for  gas,  grinding,  etc.,  objected  to, 
540 

Degeneration,  definition  of,  ii.  704 
Delegate,  restricted  function  of,  19,  36  ; 
sent  to  vote  only,  14,  20,  35  ;  sent  to 
discuss  only,  33  ;  is  superseded  by 
the  Referendum,  21  ;  becomes  an 
unfettered  representative,  37,  38,  44, 
47  j  54j  63  ;  subject  to  the  caucus, 
41 

—  meeting  unknown  in  eighteenth- 
century  Trade  Unionism,  II  ;  to 
frame  or  alter  rules,  12,  19;  sub- 
jected to  the  imperative  mandate,  14, 

20  ;   superseded  by  the  Referendum, 

21  ;      passes     into      Representative 
Assembly,  37,  46,  63 

Demand,  effect  of,  ii.  671  ;  740,  746 
Demarcation,  disputes  as  to,  ii.  508- 
527;  trades  affected  by,  509,  510; 
literature  as  to,  513 ;  remedy  for, 
520-527  ;  ancient  cases  of,  510  ;  con- 
nection of,  with  Doctrine  of  Vested 
Interests,  562 

Demetrius  the  silversmith,  ii.  564 
Democracy,  structure  and  working  of, 
Part  I.  pp.  3-141  ;  relation  of  Trade 
Unionism  to  the  future,  ii.  807-850 
Deneus,  C,  324 
Denny,  William,  293-296,  297 
Deploige,  Simon,  19 
Depression  of  trade,  remedies  for,  442- 

449;  ii.  793,  866 
Deputies,  36,  125,  126 
Derbyshire  coalminers  have  no  county 
average,   194 ;   object  to  arbitration, 
228 ;     refuse    to    work    with    non- 
unionists,    214.        See  also   Miners' 
Federation 

Derby  engineers,  346 
Devas,  C.  S.,  ii.  655,  688,  722 
Devices,  Trade  Union,  ii.  560 
Devonshire,  Duke  of,  218,  219  ;  ii.  519, 

534,  535,  530 
Dewsbury,  ii.  672 
Dicey,  A.  V.,  Professor,  ii.  800 
Dinorwic  slate  quarries,  375 


Index 


Direct  legislation,  history  of,  19  ;  Trade 
Unionists  learn  the  idea  from  Ritting- 
hausen,  21  ;  results  of,  22  ;  abandon- 
ment of,  26 ;  continuance  of,  in  North- 
umberland, etc. ,  32 ;  method  of 
among  the  London  Brushmakers,  14 

Distribution  of  Industry,  effect  of  the 
Common  Rule  on,  ii.  740-749 

District  committee,  90,  95,  96,  179,  180 

Delegate  among  the  Boilermakers, 

30 ;  among  the  Engineers,  49  ;  ap- 
pointed for  Ireland  by  Compositors,  87 

Division  of  labor,  in  the  art  of 
government,  59,  64  ;  in  cotton  manu- 
facture, 105  ;  in  engineering,  107  ; 
geographical,  125  ;  in  the  factory 
boot  industry,  403,  418  ;  by  means  of 
boys,  ii.  482-488 ;  by  means  of  women, 
498-507 ;  in  modern  shipbuilding, 
509,  519  ;  in  democracy,  844 

Dockers,  constitution  of  union  of,  47  ; 
"  go  canny "  policy  among,  307 ; 
inadequacy  of  legislation  regarding, 
365  ;  irregularity  of  employment 
among,  433  ;  ii.  757  ;  organisation  of, 
in  London,  433 ;  public  sympathy 
with,  ii.  535 ;  miserable  condition 
of,  in  London,  588  ;  effect  of  en- 
forcing Standard  Rate  among,  ii.  642, 
718  ;  incipient  Standard  among,  694 

Doctrines,  Trade  Union,  ii.  562 

Document,  the,  preface,  xi 

Domestic  servants,  ii.  674 

Donation,  a  variety  of  out  of  work  pay, 
155  ;  extension  of,  among  engineers, 
163  ;  introduction  of,  by  shipwrights, 
163  ;  effect  of  expense  of,  in  demarca- 
tion disputes,  ii.  515 

Drawers,  wages  of,  105  ;  type  of  Trade 
Unionism  required  by,  105  ;  federal 
relations  of,  123 ;  exclude  women, 
ii.  498.  See  also  Cotton  Operatives 

Dressmakers,  overtime  among,  329,  350 

Drinking  habits,  4,  5,  22  ;  diminished 
by  factory  system,  326  ;  idea  of  a 
vested  interest  in,  ii.  564,  569 

Drummond,  C.  J.,  436;  ii.  500 

Dublin,  type  of  Trade  Unionism  in,  75, 
179,  213  ;  Coopers,  75,  213  ;  Stone- 
masons, 84  ;  Shipwrights,  86 

Du  Cellier,  320,  437,  438  ;  ii.  480,  543, 
656,  718 

Dudley  Nailers,  ii.  754 

Dufferin,  Marquis  of,  64 

Dumbarton  Coalminers,  ii.  587 

Dunning,  T.  J.,  167,  337  ;  *ii.  618 

Durham  joint  boards  and  committees, 


192,  234,  238;  ii.  533;  limitation 
of  the  vend  in,  448  ;  county  average 
in,  183,  192,  193,  31 1  •  political 
sympathies  of  Trade  Unionists  of, 
271 ;  Cokemen,  35,  125;  Coalminers, 
35.  45.  125,  215,  255,  261,  355,  374, 
376,  431,  448  ;  ii.  533,  555  ;  Colliery 
Mechanics,  36,  125  ;  Deputies,  125  ; 
Enginemen,  35,  125 

Dutch,  effect  of  war  with,  437 

Dyer,  Col.  H.,  ii.  457,  777 

Dyers,  sick  pay  of,  161  ;  insist  on  time 
work,  287  ;  Trade  Union  member- 
ship among,  287 

Dyke.  See  Standard  Rate ;  policy  ot 
lowering  the,  417 

EARNINGS,  customary,  ii.  694 

Eastbourne  Laundry-workers,  ii.  727 

Economic  misconception  of  scope  of 
Trade  Unionism,  249 ;  basis  of 
accident  insurance,  375  ;  incidence 
of  compensation  for  accidents,  383  ; 
Characteristics  of  Trade  Unionism, 
Part  III.  chap.  iii.  vol.  ii.  pp.  703-806 

Economists,  the  verdict  of  the,  Part  III. 
ch.  i.  vol.  ii.  pp.  603-653 

Edge  Tool  Forgers,  ii.  459 

Edgeworth,  Professor  F.  Y.,  xviii ;  ii. 
505,  647,  648,  650,  651,  652,  653 

Edinburgh  Shoemakers,  6 ;  Tailors, 
322  ;  Compositors,  ii.  499 

Edinburgh  Review,  the,  ii.  725-747 

Education,  ii.  476,  481,  769 

Eight  Hours'  Day,  among  objects  of 
Miners'  Federation,  146,  261  ;  among 
objects  of  Gasworkers,  147  ;  general 
desire  for,  252 ;  objected  to  by 
Northumberland  and  Durham  Coal- 
miners,  261  ;  desired  in  1844,  339  ; 
agitation  for,  in  1867,  338  ;  largely 
secured  by  1897,  352  ;  literature  re- 
lating to,  324 

Election,  annual,  16,  17,  36,  50;  of 
executive  committee  by  districts,  47  ; 
controlled  by  caucus,  41  ;  after  com- 
petitive examination,  16,  197 

Elliot,  Sir  George,  448 

Ellis,  W.,  ii.  6 10,  624 

Ellison,  Judge,  229 

Emerson,  R.  W.,  ii.  726 

Employers'  benefit  societies,  371,  373, 
376 ;  ii.  528,  550,  840 

Employers'  Liability,  365-391 ;  literature 
relating  to,  366 ;  origin  of  agitation 
for,  367 ;  failure  of,  to  prevent 
accidents,  374 ;  difficulty  of  obtain- 


Index 


911 


ing  compensation  under,  380,  389  ; 
transformation  of  problem  of,  387 

Encroachment.     See  Demarcation. 

Enfranchisement,  effect  of  political,  80, 
250 ;  keenly  desired  by  Trade 
Unionists,  ii.  537 

Engagements  objected  to,  431 

Engineering  industry,  evolution  of, 
107  ;  ii.  470,  760 

Engineers,  desire  of,  for  local  autonomy, 
48  ;  recent  revolution  in  constitution 
of  Amalgamated  Society  of,  49 ; 
evolution  of  the  delegate  into  the 
representative  among,  63 ;  amalga- 
mation of,  73  ;  wide  dispersion  of, 
53,  8 1  ;  foreign  branches  of,  81  ; 
Irish  branches  of,  86,  87  ;  confusion 
between  friendly  and  dispute  benefits 
among,  94 ;  spasmodic  local  trade 
policy  of,  94  ;  dispute  with  Tyneside 
plumbers,  95 ;  ii.  509-518  ;  dispute  at 
Belfast,  96  ;  excessive  local  autonomy 
among,  96 ;  absence  of  national 
agreements  among,  97  ;  projects  of 
amalgamation  among,  109,  in  ;  ab- 
sorption of  local  societies,  no;  per- 
sistence of  sectional  unions  among, 
no;  friction  between  rival  unions, 
117  ;  impossibility  of  complete  amal- 
gamation among,  112,  130;  federal 
relations  among,  129;  refusal  of 
A.  S.  E.  to  join  federations  of,  132  ; 
ii.  523  ;  Ten  Hours'  Day  of,  340,  351, 
352 ;  declared  objects  of,  145 ; 
asserted  bankruptcy  of,  156  ;  policy 
of,  with  regard  to  Out  of  Work  benefit, 
163,  167 ;  District  Committees 
among,  1 80  ;  machinery  of,  for  Col- 
lective Bargaining,  180 ;  hours  of 
labor,  254,  255,  340,  351,  352  ;  Nine 
Hours'  Movement  of,  254,  352  ;  poli- 
tical desires  of,  264 ;  strike  of,  in 
1836,  340 ;  political  weakness  of, 
265  ;  object  to  piecework,  287,  291, 
296,  302  ;  Trade  Union  membership 
among,  287  ;  desire  of,  for  Normal 
Day,  339 ;  overtime  among,  346 ; 
desire  for  continuity  of  livelihood, 
430  ;  apprenticeship  regulations 
among,  ii.  468-473  ;  boy-labor  among, 
487  ;  demarcation  disputes  of,  509- 
518;  agreement  of,  with  Boiler- 
makers, 520 ;  refusal  of,  to  join 
Federation  of  Engineering  Trades, 
523,  525  ;  vested  interests  among, 
563  ;  seek  to  increase  mobility,  731 

Enginemen,  36,  125,  126,  252  ;  ii.  495 


Engrossing  work,  439.  See  also  De- 
marcation 

Ennis  Tailors,  85 

Entrance  to  a  Trade,  the,  vol.  ii.  Part 
II.  ch.  x.  pp.  454-507 

Equality  of  wage.     See  Standard  Rate 

Erectors,  108.     See  also  Engineers 

Erie,  Sir  W.,  ii.  857 

Estimate  work,  301 

Executive  committee  chosen  by  rota- 
tion, 7,  17,  29  ;  in  times  of  war  secret 
and  autocratic,  9  ;  nominated  by  the 
officers,  8  ;  appointed  by  the  govern- 
ing branch,  12,  17 ;  differentiated 
from  branch  committee,  17  ;  weak- 
ness of,  17,  30 ;  its  resistance  to  the 
Initiative,  23 ;  its  capture  of  the 
Referendum,  23,  26,  31  ;  its  trans- 
formation into  a  cabinet,  30,  39,  43  ; 
its  election  by  districts,  46 

Exeter  Tailors,  ii.  459 

Expenses  of  production,  best  means  of 
lowering,  ii.  733,  819 

Expert,  absence  of  the,  in  primitive 
Trade  Unionism,  8  ;  development  of, 
in  executive  work,  15,  27,  40,  49 ;  in 
legislation  and  control,  54,  57,  65, 
70 ;  function  of  the,  55,  65,  69 ; 
growth  of,  in  negotiation,  182  ;  need 
of,  in  political  action,  265  ;  dislike 
to  consult,  268  ;  future  of,  ii.  842 

FABIAN  Society,  364,  403,  445  ;  ii. 
496,  543,  772 

Factory  Acts,  development  of,  260,  310, 
348,  361,  364;  Trade  Union  support 
Of,  250,  259,  338,  364,  440 ;  ii.  537  ; 
imperfect  application  of,  to  small 
masters,  ii.  549  ;  economic  effect  of, 
ii.  608,  630,  705,  725,  727,  760,  767 

inspectors,  relations  of,  with  Trade 

Union  officials,  260 ;  opinions  on 
overtime,  330,  349 

system,  effect  of,  on  character, 

326 ;  upon  desire  for  Normal  Day, 
327 ;  in  boot  and  shoe  manufac- 
ture, 396-406  ;  strongly  supported  by 
Trade  Unions,  ii.  54°~55° 

Fagniez,  ii.  455 

Fair  Wages  clause,  failure  to  carry  out, 
ii.  555  ;  international,  867 

Fairbairn,  Sir  William,  ii.  468,  469, 
470,  471 

Farr,  Dr.  William,  ii.  637 

Farrer,  Lord,  ii.  865 

Fawcett,  Henry,  ii.  606,  618,  653 

Federalist,  the,  47  ;  ii.  656 


Index 


Federation,  use  of,  in  facilitating  repre- 
sentative institutions,  57  ;  system  of, 
among  the  Cotton  Operatives,  123, 
258 ;  among  the  Coalminers,  125 ; 
among  the  Compositors,  127;  among 
the  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives,  127; 
in  the  building  trades,  127  ;  suggested 
plan  of,  in  the  engineering  industry, 
129,  133  ;  conditions  of  success  of, 
134;  representative  government  in, 

135  ;  proportional  representation  in, 

136  ;  probable  extension  of,  in  Trade 
Union  world,    140,   270  ;  use  of,  in 
political  machinery,  258,  270  ;  result 
of,  in  demarcation  disputes,  ii.   521- 
527  ;  future  of,  837 

Fells,J.  M.,  ii.  666 

Felt  Hatmakers,  286  ;  ii.  462 

Fenwick,  John,  262 

Ferdy,  Hans,  ii.  638 

Fielding,  John,  92 

Fife  Miners,  446 

File  Cutters,  395 

Forgers,  395 

Fines,  for  breach  of  order  in  general 
meeting,  4 ;  for  refusing  office,  4, 
6,  7  ;  for  not  attending  meetings,  7  ; 
for  bad  conduct,  207  ;  among  Boiler- 
makers, 207  ;  for  dishonorable  be- 
haviour to  employer,  208 ;  discip- 
linary, objected  to,  271,  314;  effect 
of,  on  Standard  Rate,  315 ;  upon 
employers  for  neglect  of  precautions, 
384,  387  ;  often  added  to  employer's 
benefit  society,  ii.  550 

Fire  brigade  of  craftsmen,  ii.  480 

Fisheries,  389  ;  ii.  619 

Fishermen,  excluded  from  Workmen's 
Compensation  Act,  389 

Fitters.     See  Engineers 

Flint  Glass  Cutters,  ii.  462 

Glass  Makers,  nomination  of  com- 
mittee by  secretary,  8  ;  use  of  Strike 
in  Detail  by,  169  ;  provision  for  un- 
employed among,  163,  438 ;  de- 
nunciation of  non-unionists  by,  213, 
215  ;  obtain  uniform  piecework  list 
at  cost  of  lowering  some  local  rates, 
280 ;  insist  on  piecework,  286 ; 
Trade  Union  membership  among, 
286 ;  insist  on  employment  of  next 
on  the  roll,  438 ;  arrangements  for 
finding  employment,  438  ;  are  guar- 
anteed minimum  weekly  earnings, 
437  ;  apprenticeship  regulations  of, 
ii.  463,  478 ;  ii.  768 ;  progression 
among,  490;  application  by,  of 


Supply  and  Demand  to  limitation  of 
boy-labor,  573  ;  economic  effect  of 
regulations  of,  ii.  707,  711 

Foncin,  ii.  566 

Footmaker,  ii.  490 

Foreign  branches,  81 
—  trade,  ii.  733,  741,  754,  760,  780 

Foresters,  Ancient  Order  of,  18,  46, 
83,  85,  89,  101,  114,  160 

Foresters*  Miscellany,  the,  86 

Foreman,  position  of,  in  Trade  Unions, 
ii.  546 

Foxing,  439 

Fox  well,  Professor  H.  S.,  ii.  581,  689, 
786 

Frame  rent,  316 

Framework  Knitters.  See  Hosiery 
Workers 

France,  use  of  plebiscite  in,  26  ;  paper- 
makers  of,  436  ;  rotation  of  work  in, 
437»  438  5  changes  of  government  in, 
26 ;  apprenticeship  in,  ii.  455  ;  gild 
membership  in,  480  ;  system  of  giving 
out  work  in,  543  ;  decline  in  birth- 
rate in,  ii.  636 ;  monopolies  in,  708  ; 
great  strike  of  1791  in,  718;  sugar 
bounty  in,  767,  779 

Frankenstein,  Dr.  Kuno,  324,  414 ;  ii. 

54i,  543 

Freedom  of  contract,  216,  219,  249, 
327,  386;  ii.  533,  581,  847 

Freeman,  E.  A.,  3 

Free  Trade,  Appendix  II.  p.  863 

French  Polishers,  ii.  509,  516 

Friendly  benefits  in  Trade  Unionism, 
152-172 ;  effect  of,  in  demarcation 
disputes,  ii.  515  ;  possibility  of  ad- 
justing differences  of,  526 ;  effect 
of,  in  causing  hostility  to  state  insur- 
ance, 529  ;  and  to  employers'  benefit 
societies,  551  ;  relative  position  of, 
797  ;  probable  decline  of,  826 

societies,  Scottish,  83 ;  Irish 

branches  of,  85  ;  autonomy  of  Courts 
or  Lodges,  89  ;  ceremonies  of,  90 ; 
sick  pay  in,  101  ;  rotation  of  office 
in,  13 ;  governing  branch  in,  13 ; 
disapproval  of  Imperative  Mandate 
in,  46  ;  regulation  of,  1 14 ;  Trade 
Unions  as,  152 ;  alliance  of  Trade 
Unions  with,  against  state  insurance, 
ii.  528  ;  future  of,  826 

Friendly  Societies  Monthly  Magazine,  46 

Fullers,  ii.  498 

Functional  Adaptation,  definition  ol, 
ii.  704 

Fynes,  Richard,  355,  433 


Index 


913 


GAINSBOROUGH  Engineers,  346 

Gallon,  F.  W.,  xv,  9,  336,  356,  438 

Garcke,  E.,  ii.  666 

Gas  furnace,  objection  to,  412 

Gasworks,  vested  interest  in,  ii.  569 

Gas-workers,  constitution  of  union  of, 
47,  50 ;  declared  objects  of,  147 ; 
political  interests  of,  263  ;  leads  to 
introduction  of  machinery,  ii.  725 

Geneva,  education  in,  ii.  769 

George,  Henry,  ii.  619 

Germany,  accident  insurance  in,  382, 
385,  390  ;  industrial  tribunals  in,  226 ; 
objection  of  employers  in,  to  high 
wages,  401  ;  small  master  system  in, 
414  ;  apprenticeship  in,  ii.  455  ; 
Social  Democrats  of,  object  to  State 
ownership,  555  ;  syndicates  in,  448  ; 
ii.  582  ;  competition  of  coal  of, 
741  ;  of  glass  and  hardware  of,  742 ; 
sugar  bounty  in,  767.  See  also  Free 
Trade 

Gibbins,  II.  de  B.,  324 

Gibson  v.  Lawson,  ii.  854 

Giffen,  Sir  Robert,  ii.  583,  722 

Gilds,  335  ;  ii.  459,  480,  498,  510,  511 

Girdlers,  ii.  498 

Glasgow  Blacksmiths,  no  ;  Boiler- 
makers, 82,  442  ;  ii.  457  ;  Carpenters, 
340;  ii.  517,  518;  Compositors,  6, 
299>  438 ;  ii.  466  ;  Coppersmiths,  ii. 
487  ;  Cotton-spinners,  ii.  763,-  803  ; 
Engineers,  96,  352,  442  j  Harbor 
Laborers,  120;  Ropemakers,  6 ;  Ship- 
wrights, 74,  82,  442;  ii.  517,  518; 
Steel  Smelters,  82  ;  Stonemasons,  ii. 
873;  Tailors,  322,  359;  Tinplate 
Workers,  432 ;  Trades  Council  of, 
82 ;  cotton  trade  of,  ii.  762,  803 ; 
home  work  in,  ii.  539,  545,  755 

Glass  Bottle  Makers,  286,  316,  447 ; 
ii.  711 

Glass-workers.  See  Flint  Glass  Makers 
and  Glass  Bottle  Makers 

Glen,  356 

Gloucestershire  cloth  manufacture,  ii. 
764 

Glove-making,  ii.  760 

"  Go  canny"  policy,  307 

Goldasti,  ii.  565 

Goldbeaters,  ii.  462,  501 

Conner,  Professor,  ii.  618 

"Good  from  oven,"  316 

Gorgon,  the,  9 

Goschen,  Rt.  Hon.  G.  J.,  ii.  870 

Governing  branch,  n,  12,  17;  in  old 
sick  clubs,  13  ;  in  British  Empire, 
VOL.  II 


14  ;  rotation  of,  13,  17  ;  in  the 
Ancient  Order  of  Foresters,  18 

Government,  hours  in  workshops,  352  ; 
attitude  of  Trade  Unions  towards 
employment  by,  ii.  553  ;  bias  of 
officials  of,  555  ;  attitude  of  Trade 
Unions  towards  compulsory  insurance 
by,  529  ;  bias  of,  to  cheapness,  819 

Graham,  Sir  James,  ii.  565 

Grand  National  Consolidated  Trades 
Union,  12,  139 

Gravesend  Watermen,  437 

Great  Harwood  Cotton  -  weavers,  79, 
280 

Green,  C.  H.,  370 

Mrs.  J.  R.,  ii.  480 

Greg,  R.  H.,  338 

Greville,  C.  C.  F.,  ii.  565 

Griffiths  v.  Earl  of  Dudley,  370 

Grindery,  claim  for  free,  ii.  540 

Grinding  money,  175*  3J3 

Gross,  Dr.  Charles,  ii.  855 

Guile,  Daniel,  157 

Gun-barrels,  welding  of,  ii.  724 

G  union,  George,  ii.  696 

HADFIELD,  R.  A.,  324 

Halesowen  Nailers,  ii.  548 

Half-time  system,  proposed  extension 
of,  ii.  769 

Hall,  Rev.  Robert,  171 
—  W.  Clarke,  363 

Halle,  E.  von,  ii.  709 

Halliday,  Thomas,  382 

Hammermen,  ii.  509 

Handloom  Weavers,  strike  of  Scottish, 
10;  travelling  benefit  of,  162;  applica- 
tions for  legal  fixing  of  wages,  250, 
337  ;  indifference  of,  to  Normal  Day. 
337  J  gradual  degradation  of,  414 ; 
irregularity  of  employment  among, 

434 

Handrailing,  284 
Harcourt,    Rt.    Hon.    Sir   W.    V.,    ii. 

538 

Hardy,  R.  P.,  101  ;   ii.  638 

Harrison,  Frederic,  ii.  618 

Hatters,  early  "congresses"  of,  n  ; 
insist  on  piecework,  286 ;  Trade 
Union  membership  among,  286  ; 
London  hat  finishers  work  by  time, 
336  ;  attitude  of,  towards  Normal 
Day,  336  ;  night-work  prohibited  by 
mediaeval,  335  ;  arrangements  for 
finding  employment,  438  ;  prevent 
employer  choosing  workman,  438 ; 
apprenticeship  regulations  of,  ii.  463  ; 

3   N 


914 


Index 


economic  effect  of  regulations  of,  7°7- 
See  Felt  Hat  Makers 

Hattersley  composing  machine,  408 

Health,  slow  growth  of  attention  to, 
355 ;  economic  importance  .of,  ii. 
710,  717  ;  unprotected,  771,  785 

Hearts  of  Oak  Benefit  Society,  101  ;  ii. 
636 

Helpers,  Boilermakers',  291, 296 ;  ii.  481 

Herkner,  Heinrich,  ii.  789 

Ilexham  Carpenters,  53 

Higgling  of  the  Market,  the,  vol.  ii. 
Part  III.  ch.  ii.  pp.  654-702 

Hill,  Frank,  ii.  458 

Frederic,  281 

Hingley,  Sir  B.,  234 

Hobson,  C,  434 

J.  A.,  ii.  628 

Hodgskin,  T. ,  403 

Holders-up,  admitted  to  United  Society 
of  Boilermakers,  128;  ii.  491 

Holland,  Dr.  G.  Calvert,  ii.  614 
Lord,  ii.  567 

Holmes,  David*,  201,  259 

Home  Rule,  vi,  88  ;  ii.  833 

work,  abolition  of,  desired,  252, 

263  ;  causes  indifference  to  Normal 
Day,  325,  342  ;  effect  of,  on  personal 
character,  326 ;  imperfect  legislation 
with  regard  to,  365  ;  struggle  of, 
against  factory,  414  ;  extreme  irregu- 
larity of,  433  ;  Trade  Union  objec- 
tion to,  ii.  539  j  Utopian  picture  of, 
541 ;  demoralising  conditions  of,  542  ; 
causes  degradation  of  wages,  543  ; 
gradual  decline  of,  543  ;  parasitic 
nature  of,  749-766  ;  abolition  of,  840 

Horner,  Francis,  ii.  567 

Horrocks'  longcloth,  ii.  690 

Hosiery  workers,  Mutual  Insurance 
among,  171 ;  applied  for  legal  fixing  of 
wages,  250  ;  desire  to  regulate  Home 
Work,  263 ;  insist  on  piecework,  286 ; 
Trade  Union  membership  among, 
286  ;  indifference  of,  to  Normal  Day, 
335  ;  policy  of,  to  women  workers,  ii. 
502 

Hours  of  labor,  cases  of  increase  of, 
353,  441  ;  ii.  794 ;  in  mediaeval 
crafts,  335  ;  among  home  workers, 
ii.  544  ;  of  Bookbinders,  336,  352  ; 
of  Brushmakers,  343  ;  of  Building 
Trades,  340,  352 ;  of  Carpenters, 
255.  352  5  of  Coalminers,  255,  339  ; 
ii.  583  ;  of  Chain  and  Nail  Opera- 
tives, ii.  583  ;  of  Compositors,  342  ; 
of  Coopers,  336,  341  ;  of  Cotton 


Operatives,  25$,  338,  346,  431  ;  of 
Dressmakers,  329,  350  ;  of  Engineers, 
254,  255,  340,  346,  352  ;  of  Flint 
Glass  Makers,  ii.  583  ;  of  Hatters, 
33 5>  336  ;  of  Laundry  -  women,  ii. 
583  ;  of  Saddlers,  336,  352 ;  of 
Sheffield  trades,  344  ;  of  Shoemakers, 
342 ;  of  Shipwrights,  341,  352 ;  of 
Stonemasons,  352  ;  of  Tailors,  336, 
352.  See  also  Normal  Day 

House  of  Call,  9,  437 

of  Lords'  Committee  on  the 

Sweating  System,  364 ;  ii.  543,  548, 
588,  589,  655,  765,  771,  772 

Howell,  George,  158;  ii.  855 

Hoyt,  H.  M.,   ii.  866 

Hughes,  Judge  T.,  ii.  486 

Hull  Compositors,  ii.  466 

Humidity  of  weaving  sheds,  252,  272, 
358,  364,  386 

Hunter,  Joseph,  ii.  458 

Huskisson,  Rt.  Hon.  W.,  447 

IMPERATIVE  Mandate,  use  of,  14, 
20 ;  superseded  by  Referendum, 
21  ;  abandoned  by  Northumberland 
miners,  33  ;  not  used  among  Cotton 
Operatives,  39 ;  absent  from  Miners' 
Federation,  43 ;  gradual  abandon- 
ment of,  in  revision  of  rules,  46,  63 

Implications  of  Trade  Unionism,  the, 
vol.  ii.  Part  II.  ch.  xii.  pp.  528-558 

Imports  increased  by  an  increase  in 
exports,  ii.  742,  763,  863.  See  also 
Free  Trade 

Income,  national,  445  ;  ii.  643 

Indentures,  ii.  454,  460 

Independent  Labor  Party,  primitive 
democracy  of,  35 

Index  number,  ii.  577 

Individual  Bargaining,  origin  of  term, 
173  ;  description  of,  173  ;  frequent 
result  of  piecework  in  some  trades, 
291-304  ;  difficulty  of,  with  regard  to 
hours  of  labor,  327  ;  impossibility  of, 
with  regard  to  sanitation  and  safety, 
354  ;  with  respect  to  new  processes 
and  machinery,  404,  408,  411  ;  inci- 
dental to  annual  hirings,  431  ;  in- 
evitable with  Home  Work,  435  ; 
inadmissible  with  demarcation  dis- 
putes, ii.  519  ;  inevitable  with  Home 
Work,  544 ;  injurious  effect  of,  uni- 
versally assumed,  560 

Individualism,  in  Trade  Unionism,  ii. 
598,  832 

Industrial     Insurance,    regulation     of, 


Index 


915 


114  ;  comparison  of,  with  Trade 
Union  benefits,  154 

Infectious  disease,  fear  of,  362 

Inglis,  J.f  ii.  457,  481 

Ingram,  J.  K.,  ii.  546 

Initiative,  the,  21  ;  results  of,  24 ; 
gradual  abandonment  of,  25  ;  reten- 
tion of,  among  Northumberland  Coal- 
miners,  32  ;  produces  instability  of 
policy,  24,  33  ;  fails  to  secure  popular 
control,  33,  6 1 

Inquest  on  accidents,  384 

Inspection,  Government,  increase  in, 
377  ;  failure  of,  with  Home  Work 
and  Small  Masters ;  ii.  547,  549 

Insurance,  experience  as  to  sickness  in, 
101  ;  advantage  of  branch  as  jury 
in,  101  ;  evil  of  competition  in,  113  ; 
legal  regulation  of,  114;  Trade 
Unionism  a  form  of,  152  ;  lack  of 
study  of  insurance  side  of  Trade 
Unionism,  155  ;  against  accidents  by 
employers,  375,  383,  389  ;  compul- 
sory, objected  to,  385  ;  ii.  529 

Integration  of  processes,  353 

Interest,  effect  of  rate  of,  ii.  610-632  ; 
low  rate  of,  on  watered  capital,  667 

Interpretation,  questions  of,  183 ;  among 
boot  and  shoe  operatives,  189  ;  ex- 
amples of,  among  coalminers,  311  ; 
among  cotton  operatives,  312 

Interunion  relations,  vol.  i.  Part  I.  ch.  iv. 
pp.  104-141 

Ipswich  Engineers,  346 

Ireland,  survival  of  spirit  of  local 
monopoly  in,  75  ;  irregularities  of 
Trade  Union  branches  in,  83  ;  num- 
ber of  branches  in,  87 ;  absence  of 
Irish  national  unions,  87  ;  Home  Rule 
for,  22,  84,  88  ;  child  labor  in,  ii.  769 

Iron  bedsteads,  ii.  578,  747 

Ironclad  contracts,  ii.  684 

Iron  dressers,  17 

Ironfounders,  drinking  allowed  at  meet- 
ings of,  5  ;  preference  for  rotation  of 
governing  branch,  13;  long  stay  in 
London,  17  ;  mode  of  electing  execu- 
tive, 17  ;  delegate  meetings  of,  19  ; 
adopt  Referendum,  21  ;  experience 
of  Direct  Legislation  among,  23 ; 
expansion  of  union  of,  72  >  separate 
organisation  of  Scotch  and  English, 
83  ;  proposal  to  include,  in  A.  S.  E., 
112,  130;  quotation  from  first  rules 
of,  112;  rivalry  between  unions  of, 
115;  attempt  to  increase  benefits 
and  reduce  income,  1 16 ;  federal 


relations  of,  130,  134 ;  declared 
objects  of,  145  ;  exhaustion  of  funds 
of,  155  ;  nature  of  friendly  benefits 
of,  145,  157,  170;  out  of  work  pay 
among  Scottish,  164  ;  machinery  for 
Collective  Bargaining  among,  180 ; 
political  desires  of,  264 ;  object  to 
piecework,  287,  302  ;  object  to  de- 
ductions for  spoiled  work,  316 ;  Trade 
Union  membership  among,  287  ;  urge 
members  not  to  resist  machinery. 
394  ;  forbid  long  engagements,  431  ; 
attempt  to  restrict  boy-labor,  ii.  487 
Ironmoulders.  See  Ironfounders 
Iron  Trades  Employers'  Association, 

I3'»  353,  362 

Irregularity.     See  Continuity 
Irwin,  Margaret  H.,  ii.  539,  545,  756 
Ismay,  Thomas,  ii.  534 
Ithuriel,  ii.  729 

"JACK  Cade  legislation,"  ii.  565 

Jaeger  clothing,  ii.  683 

E.  L.,  324 

James,  John,  162 

Sir  Henry  (now   Lord  James  of 

Hereford),  186,  190,  231,  235,  241  ; 
ii.  484,  485,  776 

fan-old,  J.,  ii.  568 

"arrow,  ii.  513 
cans,  J.  S.,  223 
efferson,  ii.  841 

'enkin,  Fleeming,  166,  357 ;  ii.  618, 
646,  647,  821 

Jerry  builders,  objected  to,  ii.  549,  792 

Jevons,  W.  S.,  3o7>.355>  377;  "•  657 

Jews,  in  bootmaking  form  separate 
branches,  127  ;  standard  of,  ii.  687, 
698  ;  in  clothing  trade,  744 

Jobez,  ii.  566 

Joiners,  ancient  demarcation  with  Car- 
penters, ii.  510.  See  also  Carpenters 

Joining,  system  of,  ii.  475 

Joint  boards  or  committees,  long  advo- 
cated, 185  ;  experience  of,  in  boot 
and  shoe  manufacture,  185-192,  209  ; 
in  coalmining,  192-194,  234  ;  in 
cotton  manufacture,  194-204  ;  in  iron 
manufacture,  205,  211,  231  ;  under 
South  Wales  Sliding  Scale,  209 ; 
proposal  to  give  legal  powers  to,  218  ; 
ii.  534  ;  objection  of  Cotton  Opera- 
tives to,  244  ;  in  Victoria,  246  ;  ii. 
488 ;  in  New  Zealand,  214  ;  ii.  814 

Jones,  Lloyd,  ii.  587 

Richard,  ii.  618 

Jude,  Martin,  339 


916 


Index 


Judge,  James,  II 

Jupp,  E.  B.,  ii.  480,  510 

Jurancles,  ii.  570 

Jury,  the  branch  acting  as,  100 

KATZENSTEIN,  Louis,  ii.  776 

Keighley  Engineers,  346 

Kemble,  Fanny,  ii.  505 

Kendal  Stonemasons,  98 ;  Woolcombers, 

162 

Kennedy,  John,  326 
Kentish  Papermakers,  8,   ii,   12,  420, 

436  ;  ii.  462,  533,  579,  707,  761 
Kettle,  Sir  Rupert,  185  ;  ii.  580,  708 
Keufer,  Auguste,  ii.  776 
Keymaster,  6 
Kidderminster  Carpet-weavers,  286  ;  ii. 

481,  486 

Kingswood  boot  trade  board,  187,  188 
Knight,  Robert,  30,  132,  204,  228  ;  ii. 

457 
Knobsticks,  249 

LABOR  colonies,  ii.  787 

Department.    See  Board  of  Trade 

Exchanges,  402 

Laborers,  weakness  of  organisations  of, 
121 ;  liability  of,  to  chasing,  305,  306 ; 
objectionable  by-laws  of,  304  ;  desire 
payment  for  overtime,  340  ;  progress 
to  be  slaters  and  bricklayers,  ii.  489  ; 
relation  of,  to  demarcation  disputes, 
525  ;  employment  of,  on  machines, 
471,  524,  563.  See  Dockers,  Gas- 
workers,  Builders'  Laborers 

Labour  Leader,  the,  36 

Lacemakers,  286  ;  ii.  463,  761 

Laferriere,  26 

Lakeman,  351 

Lalor,  42 

Lanarkshire  Coalminers,  446  ;  ii.  587 

Lancashire  Coalminers,  43,  45,  53,  194, 
339,  372,  374;  Trade  Unionists,  poli- 
tical sympathies  of,  271  ;  ii.  538,  838 

Landesgemeinde,  the  Swiss,  3,  7>  22 

Land  nationalisation  at  Trade  Union 
Congress,  271  ;  not  necessarily  de- 
sired by  Trade  Unionists,  ii.  555,  832 

Lassalle,  Ferdinand,  403 

Lasters.    See  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives 

Laundries,  365  ;  ii.  583,  727 

Laurence,  Edwin,  292 

Lawson,  Sir  Wilfrid,  ii.  564 

Laziness  of  mankind,  ii.  726 

Leather -workers,  travelling  benefit 
among,  162  :  use  of  Strike  in  Detail 
by,  167  ;  custom  of  patrimony  among, 


ii.  460  ;  ancient  demarcation  among, 
5io 

Lecky,  W.  E.  H.,  26,  177,  214,  221, 
282,  329;  ii.  559,  717 

Leeds,  Boot  Trade  Board  of,  187  ; 
clothing  factories  in,  ii.  765  ;  Brush - 
makers,  13;  Builders'  Laborers,  304  ; 
Compositors,  ii.  466  ;  Leather-work- 
ers, 168  ;  Stuff  Pressers,  ii.  463 

Leek  Trimming  Weavers,  ii.  463 

Lefevre,  Rt.  Hon.  G.  Shaw,  169 

Legal  enactment,  as  a  Trade  Union 
method,  Part  II.  chap.  iv.  pp.  247-278 ; 
early  use  of,  248  ;  recent  increase  of, 
250  ;  variety  of  demands  for,  252  ; 
characteristics  of,  253 ;  machinery 
for,  257-278  ;  in  support  of  Standard 
Rate,  309 ;  not  possible  in  apprentice- 
ship, ii.  479  ;  nor  against  boy-labor, 
488  ;  economics  of,  796-806 

position  of  Trade  Unions,  114; 

"•  533  J  as  affecting  their  actuarial 
position,  154;  as  affecting  enforce- 
ment of  collective  agreements,  218  ; 
ii.  534 ;  Appendix  I.  pp.  853-862 

Legalisation  of  Trade  Unions,  limited 
character  of,  154  ;  objection  to  com- 
pletion of,  ii.  530 

Leicester  Boot  and    Shoe   Operatives, 

10,  401,  418  ;  ii.  483 
Leslie,  T.  E.  Cliffe,  ii.  618 
Levasseur,  ii.  455 

Levelling-up,  policy  of,  321  ;  ii.  835 
Liberty,  definition  of,  ii.  847 
Lightermen.     See  Watermen 
Limitation  of  the  vend,  448  ;  of  output, 

11.  708.       See    also    Restriction    of 
Numbers 

Lincoln  Engineers,  346  ;  Fullers,  ii.  498 
Linotype,  407;  ii.  464,  571,  733 
List,  Friedrich,  ii.  865 
Lister  and  Company,  ii.  667 
Lithographic  Printers,  287  ;  ii.  463 
Liverpool     Boilermakers,     300,     314  ; 
building  trades,  340 ;  Coopers,  394  ; 
Dockers,  307;  Engineers,  117;  ii.  515; 
Ironfounders,     117;     Packing-case 
Makers,   395  ;    Painters,    432 ;    Sail- 
makers,  75  ;  Shipwrights,  5,  7 ;  Stone- 
masons, 20,  340,  352  ;  Tailors,  ii.  544 ; 
Tinplate  workers,  300 
Livesey,  George,  ii.  534,  777 
Living  Wage,   Doctrine  of  a,  ii.    562, 

582-597,  766,  816 
Lloyd,  H.  D.,  ii.  709 
—  Sampson,  ii.  866 
Local  option  in  drink  traffic,  ii.  564 


Index 


917 


Locomotive  Enginemen  and  Firemen, 
constitution  of  Union  of,  46,  50.  See 
also  Railway  Servants 
Log,  Tailors',  279,  283  ;  Scottish,  322 
London,  absence  of  boy-labor  in,  ii. 
489,  770 ;  hours  of  labor  in,  352 ;  fail- 
ure of  Factory  Acts  in,  351  ;  ii.  549  ; 
high  wages  of,  321  ;  Trades  Council 
of,  266  ;  political  sympathies  of  men 
in,  271  ;  Bookbinders,  131,  336,  352; 
Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives,  10,  322  ; 
Bricklayers,  ii.  489, 549;  Brush  makers, 
4,  14,  343  ;  ii.  502  ;  Building  Trades, 
178,  340,  352;  ii.  480,  489;  ii. 
800 ;  Carmen,  ii.  800 ;  Carpenters, 
321  ;  Compositors,  10,  127,  299,  314, 
342,  407,  436,  438;  ii.  460,  465, 
468,  499,  500,  502,  507,  873; 
Coopers,  336,  341  ;  Dockers,  47, 

365,  433  5  "•  535,  588,  718,  757,  78.3, 
791;  Engineers,  313,  340,  352;  ii. 
469  ;  Goldbeaters,  ii.  501  ;  Hatters, 
ii,  321,  336  ;  Plasterers,  360  ;  Plum- 
bers, ii.  475 ;  Sailmakers,  7 ;  Saddlers, 
336»  352 ;  Shipwrights,  341,  438  ; 
Silver  -  workers,  ii.  800 ;  Stone 
Carvers,  360 ;  Stonemasons,  77,  279, 
313  ;  Tailors,  9,  264,  279,  336,  352  ; 
Watermen,  437 ;  Woolstaplers,  4, 
ii 

and  North-Western  Railway  Com- 
pany, 372,  374  ;  ii.  691 

Brighton,  and  South  Coast  Rail- 
way Company,  374 

County  Council,  attempts  in,  to 

confine  contracts  to  London  firms, 
76 ,  refusal  of,  to  conform  to  Stone- 
masons' rules,  78 ;  minimum  wage 
of,  ii.  774 

School  of  Economics  and  Political 

Science,  9,  19,  336,  356;  ii.  642 

Longe,  F.  D.,  ii.  618 

Longfield,  Montifort,  ii.  618 

Looking-glass  Factories,  ii.  708 

Loom  rent,  316,  434  ;  ii.  840 

Loria,  Achilla,  56 

Lot,  choice  by,  7,  442 

Lothians  Engineman,  ii.  873 

Lotteries,  ii.  569 

Lowell,  47 

Lucifer-match  Makers,  ii.  588 

Luddites,  the,  220 

Ludlow,  J.  M.,  159;  ii.  618 

Lump  Work,  302 

Lushington,  Sir  Godfrey,  ii.  544 

Lying-in  benefit,  ii.  638,  642 

Lynch,  J.,  291 


Lynch  law,  213 
Lyttelton,  Hon.  A.,  ii.  861 

MACCLESFIELD  Silk-weavers,  434 

Macleod,  H.  U.,  ii.  618 

M'Corquodale,  ii.  499 

M'Culloch,  John  Ramsay,  ii.  604,  606, 
607,  608,  609,  610,  617,  623,  633, 
634,  635,  653,  695,  696,  722,  723, 
868 

Macdonald,  Alexander,  261,  339,  367, 
368,  372  . 

Machine-minders,  108 ;  ii.  524,  525. 
See  also  Engineers 

Machinery,  increases  mental  strain  of 
work,  289  ;  and  speed  of  work,  399, 
409  ;  policy  of  Trade  Unions  towards, 
392-429 ;  specially  encouraged  by 
Cotton  Operatives,  408-410 ;  intro- 
duction of,  a  matter  for  Collective 
Bargaining,  41 1  ;  effect  of,  on  engin- 
eering trade,  ii.  471  ;  employment  of 
laborers  in  connection  with,  471, 
524,  525,  563 

Mackie,  350 

Maine,  Sir  Henry,  ii.  580 

Malingering  in  sick  benefit  societies,  101 

Mai  thus,  T.  R.,  ii.  633,  641 

Malthusianism,  ii.  632-643 

Manchester  G^iardian,  ii.  466 

Boot  Trade  Board,  187  ;  Trades 

Council,  266 ;  Building  Trades, 
442  ;  Bricklayers,  304  ;  Compositors, 
5,  438  ;  ii.  466  ;  Engineers,  438  ; 
Saddlers,  439 ;  Slaters,  ii.  489 ; 
Stonemasons,  78  ;  Tinplate  Workers, 
300  ;  Upholsterers,  ii.  467 

Manley,  Thomas,  437 

Mann,  Tom,  in,  133,  346 

Manningham  Mills,  ii.  667 

Marcet,  Mrs.,  ii.  608 

Marginal  cost  of  production  affected  by 
Common  Rule,  ii.  730  ;  not  conclu- 
sive as  to  distribution  of  industry,  73 J 

utility  determines  value  and  wages, 

ii.  645,  779  ;  under  Common  Rules, 
also  the  sphere  of  employment,  719 

Marriage-rate,  ii.  636 

Marshall,  Professor  Alfred,  354,  393  ; 
ii.  546,  604,  618,  621,  622,  627,  643, 
644,  645,  648,  649,  651,  652,  657, 
666,  722,  723 

Martineau,  Harriet,  ii.  485,  608,  653, 
752 

Martin-Saint-Le'on,  E.,  ii.  455 

Marx,  Karl,  285,  328,  337,  402,  403, 
418;  ii.  725 


9i8 


Index 


Masham,  Lord,  ii.  667 

Masons.     See  Stonemasons 

Massachusetts,  early  use  of  Referendum 
in,  19  ;  boot  factories  of,  400,  413  ; 
ii.  747  ;  primary  assemblies  legally 
regulated  in,  42  ;  report  on  arbitra- 
tion in,  223  ;  limitation  of  families 
and  supplementary  wage-earners  in, 
ii.  641  ;  manufactures  of,  729 

Mast  and  Blockmakers,  ii.  509 

Masterpiece,  ii.  455] 

Matchbox-makers,  365 

Mather,  W.,  ii.  727 

Mavor,  Professor,  ii.  618 

Mawdsley,  James,  199,  201,  228,  230, 
259,  409 

Maximum,  ii.  716 

Mayhew,  Henry,  437 

Meeting,  general  government  by,  3,  8, 

10,  36,   40 ;    drinking  and   smoking 
at,  5 

Melson,  John,  printer,  gets  idea  of 
Referendum  from  continental  demo- 
crats, 21 

Menger,  Dr.  Anton,  403 

Merchant  Shipping  Acts,  364 

Method,  the,  of  Mutual  Insurance,  vol. 
i.  Part  II.  ch.  i.  pp.  152-172;  of 
Collective  Bargaining,  vol.  i.  Part 

11.  ch.   ii.    pp.    173-221  ;    of  Legal 
Enactment,  vol.   i.    Part   II.  ch.   iv. 
pp.  247-278;  economic  characteristics 
of  each,  ii.  796-806 

Midland  Iron  Board,  205,  21 1,  231 

Railway  Company,  ii.  551 

Mill,  John  Stuart,  ii.  568,  569,  604, 
605,  610,  612,  618,  620,  624,  636, 
638,  649,  653,  688,  695,  696,  711, 
712,  714,  730,  752,  759,  809,  832, 
869 

Millwrights,  107 ;  ii.  460,  468.  See 
also  Engineers 

Miners'  Federation  of  Great  Britain, 
adoption  of  representative  institutions 
by,  38,  43  ;  federal  form  of,  51,  57  ; 
concentration  of,  53  >  declared  ob- 
jects of,  146  ;  object  to  arbitration, 
228,  244 ;  political  activity  of,  260 
263  ;  leading  position  of,  in  Trade 
Union  Congress,  278 ;  policy  with 
regard  to  output,  449  ;  order  a  week's 
holiday,  449  ;  demand  of,  for  a  Living 
Wage,  ii.  589.  See  also  Coalminers 

Parliament,  the,  description  of, 

44 ;  composition  of,  57 

Mines  inspectors,  increase  in,  368, 
377 


Mines  Regulation  Acts,  250,  261,  263, 
309,  368,  384,  39.0  ;  ii.  728 

Minimum,  the  National,  ii.  766-784 

Mir,  the,  ii.  808 

Mobility  of  labor  established,  74  ;  ob- 
jections to,  75  ;  hostile  to  long  en- 
gagements, 431  ;  inconsistent  with 
employers'  benefit-societies,  ii.  551  ; 
obstacles  to  international,  630 ;  Trade 
Unions  try  to  increase,  731 

Moeser,  Justus,  347,  356 

Mogul  S.S.  Co.  v.  Macgregor,  Gow, 
and  Co.,  ii.  689,  857 

Monopoly,  local  trade,  73 ;  among 
Shipwrights,  73,  75  ;  among  Sail- 
makers,  74,  75 ;  among  Stonemasons, 
75,  77  ;  among  Coopers,  75  ;  among 
Carpenters,  76  ;  among  Shoemakers, 
78  ;  in  Ireland,  75  ;  manifestation  of, 
in  demarcation  disputes,  ii.  514; 
growth  of,  in  modern  times,  582  ;  an 
outcome  of  freedom,  689 

Morals,  influence  of  work  on,  ii.  497  ; 
effect  of  Home  Work  on,  542 

Morison,  J.  Cotter,  ii.  632 

Morisseaux,  Charles,  223 

Morley,  Rt.  Hon.  John,  449 ;  ii.  538 

Morpeth  Coalminers,  264 ;  Tailors, 
264 

Morris,  William,  ii.  50x3 

Morrison,  C.,  173;  ii.  606,  614 

Mosses,  119 

Mule-spinners.     See  Cot  ton- spinners 

Mundella,  Rt.  Hon.  A.  J.,  185,  223  ;  ii. 

723. 
Municipal     employment,     relation     of 

Trade  Unionism  to,  ii.  556 
Musee  Social,  160,  366 
Music     printers,    incipient    federation 

among,  127 
Mutual  Insurance,  the  method  of,  Part 

II.  ch.  i.  p.  152 

NAPOLEON,  use  of  plebiscite  by,  2b 
Nash,  Vaughan,  433  ;  ii.  589 
Nasmith,  Joseph,  ii.  732,  733,  754 
Nasmyth,  Joseph,  ii.  573 
National   agreements,    176,    218,  256; 

of  Cotton  Operatives,  97,  176,   256; 

of  Boilermakers,   97,    177  ;  of  Boot 

and  Shoe  Operatives,    186;  of  Iron 

and  Steel  Workers,  205 
Association     of    Employers     of 

Labor,  226 

•  Dividend,  the,  ii.  643 

—  Minimum,  the,  ii.  766-784 

—  Union  of  Miners,  261 


Index 


919 


National  Union  of  Teachers,  ii.  826 
Nationalisation    of  minerals,    45 ;    ii. 

555 

Negotiator,  development  of  the  skilled, 
181  ;  effect  on  extension  of  piece- 
work, 303 

Negro,  absence  of  minimum  in,  ii.  698 

Neo-Malthusianism,  ii.  638 

Neuchatel,  ii.  770 

New  Processes  and  Machinery,  vol.  i. 
Part  II.  ch.  viii.  pp.  392-428 

unions,  declared  objects  of,  147  ; 

practice  of,  with  regard  to  benefits, 
153;  effect  of  absence  of  friendly 
benefits  in,  159;  supposed  exceptional 
exclusiveness  of,  214 

Zealand,  Conciliation  Act  of,  246  ; 

ii.  814 

Newcastle,  old  gilds  of,  ii.  510;  de- 
marcation disputes  at,  ii.  510-518; 
Carpenters,  53;  ii.  510;  Shipwrights, 
74;  ii.  511  ;  Engineers,  95,  178;  ii. 
512;  Plumbers,  95;  ii.  512 

Newcastle  Chronicle,  the,  ii.  513 

Leader,  the,  204 

Newmarch,  William,  282 

Newport  Engineers,  358 

Newspaper  printers  in  federal  union, 
127  ;  use  linotype,  407  ;  guaranteed 
a  minimum  of  earnings,  408,  436 ; 
restriction  of  apprenticeship  among, 
ii.  466 

Newspapers,  competition  among,  ii.  720 

Newton,  William,  no,  in,  133,  134, 
340 

Newton  -  le  -  WTillows,  women  learn 
printing  at,  ii.  499 

Nicholson,  Professor  J.  S  ,  ii.  618,  626, 
646,  727 

Niger,  ii.  680 

Nightwork  prohibited  in  mediaeval 
crafts,  335  ;  for  women,  329 

Nine  Hours'  Day,  of  Cotton  Operatives, 
250,  254,  257,  338;  of  Engineers, 
254,  352 ;  ii.  732 ;  of  Carpenters, 
256;  of  Stonemasons,  340,  351,  352 

Nitti,  F.,  ii.  637 

Non-unionists,  compulsory  inclusion  of, 
within  Sliding  Scale,  209  ;  violence 
to,  213  ;  refusal  to  work  with,  214  ; 
ii.  533  ;  virtual  compulsion  of,  534 

Normal  Day,  Part  II.  ch.  vi.  pp.  324- 
353 ;  a  modern  demand,  325 ;  in- 
fluence of,  upon  wages,  329-335  ; 
diversity  of  opinion  as  to,  335-344  ; 
effect  of  overtime  in  connection  with, 
341,  344;  necessary  rigidity  of,  347- 


351  ;   successive  reductions  of,  351  ; 
tendency  of,  to  uniformity,  353 
North-Eastern    Railway   Company,   ii. 

777 

North,  the  Lord  Keeper,  355 

of  England  Manufactured  Iron 

Board,  205,  21 1,  231  ;  ii.  533 

Northampton  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives, 
78j  393  J  Boot  Trade  Board,  209,  231 

Northumberland  joint  boards  and  com- 
mittees, 192,  234,  238,  311  ;  ii.  533, 
limitation  of  the  vend  in,  448, 
county  average  in,  183,  192,  193, 
311  ;  political  sympathies  of  Trade 
Unionists  in,  271  ;  Coalminers,  32, 
125,  215,  255,  261,  311,  355,  374, 
432,  448 ;  ii.  533,  555,  583  ;  Coke- 
men,  125  ;  Colliery  Mechanics,  125  ; 
Deputies,  125  ;  Enginemen,  125 

Norwich  Brushmakers,  394 ;  boot 
trade  board,  189 

Nottingham,  Hosiery  Board,  223  ;  ii. 
723  ;  Coalminers,  45,  58  ;  Hosiers, 
223  ;  Lacemakers,  286;  ii.  463,  761 ; 
Bricklayers,  360 

OASTLER,  T.,  250,  364 
Oddfellows'  Magazine,  the,  83,  IOI 
Officers  chosen  by  rotation,  7  :  by  lot, 
7  ;   nominated  by  other  officers,  8 ; 
by    tacit    approval,    9 ;    after    com- 
petitive  examination,    16 ;    annually 
elected,   16,  36,  50;   obtain  perma- 
nence of  tenure,  16,  40,  41,  50 
Offices,  sale  of,  in  Switzerland,  7,  22 ; 
proposed  among  the  Stonemasons,  22 
Old  age,  provision  for,  by  Trade  Unions, 
152-161;    objection   to   compulsory 
insurance  for,  ii.  529  ;  pensions,  827 

men,  employment  of,  ii.  717 

Oldham,  Cotton-spinners,  41,  92,   125, 
264,    289  ;     ii.    729 ;    Ironfounders, 
116;  Plumbers,  264;  Carpenters,  264 
Open  trades,  ii.  473 
Outdoor  relief,  effect  of,  426  ;  ii.  718 
Out  of  Work  pay  given  only  by  Trade 
Unions,  100,  160;  municipal  attempts 
to  provide,   160 ;   fundamental  posi- 
tion of,  in  Trade  Union  Mutual  In- 
surance,   161  ;    economic    effect    of, 
163  ;  use  of,  to  abolish  underground 
workshops,  359  ;  effect  of,  in  demarc- 
ation disputes,  ii.  515  ;  future  of,  ii. 
828 

Overlap,  ii.  519.    See  also  Demarcation 

Overlookers,    wages   of,    105  ;    federal 

relations  of,  123,  258  ;  type  of  Trade 


920 


Index 


Unionism  required  by,  105  ;  strategic 
position  of,  ii.  479.  See  Cotton  Oper- 
atives 

Over-production,  448 

Oversteaming,  252,  272,  358,  364,  386 

Overtime,  264,  341-351,  439 

Owen,  Robert,  101,  250,  402,  403  ;  ii. 
608,  868 

Owenite  Trade  Unionism,  constitutional 
form  of,  12;  inherent  impracticability 
of,  1 39  ;  economic  basis  of,  402 ; 
was  followed  by  Doctrine  of  Supply 
and  Demand,  ii.  572 

PACKING-CASE  Makers,  395  ;  ii.  486 

Painters,  imperfect  organisation  of,  81  ; 
federal  relations  of,  132,  134  ;  work- 
ing rules  of,  175 ;  forbid  long  en- 
gagements, 432 ;  ancient  gild  of,  ii. 
480  ;  demarcation  disputes  of,  509 

Paley,  ii.  454 

Pallion  Works,  dispute  at,  ii.  563 

Pamphleteer ;  the,  ii.  455 

Papermakers,  nomination  of  committee 
by  officers,  8 ;  early  rules  of,  1 1  ; 
hierarchy  of  non-elective  authorities 
among,  12 ;  attitude  of,  towards 
machine-made  paper,  420;  rates  of 
wages  of,  421  ;  frequent  arbitrations 
of,  420 ;  increased  efficiency  of, 
423;  enforce  the  "six  days'  custom," 

436 

apprenticeship  regulations  among, 

ii.  462  ;  compulsory  Trade  Unionism 
among,  533  ;  virtual  alliance  of,  with 
employers  to  check  competition,  579, 
707  ;  in  France,  708 

Parasitic  trades,  ii.  749-766 

Paris,  the  Parliament  of,  ii.  565; 
poverty  and  birth-rate  of,  637  ;  pro- 
vision for  funerals  in,  827 

Parliamentary  agent,  boot  operatives 
support,  147 

Committee  of  Trade  Union  Con- 
gress, 265-278 ;  action  of,  with  re- 
gard to  Employers'  Liability,  369,  373 

Particulars  clause,  252,  271,  310 

Partnering,  ii.  475 

Patents,  ii.  682 

Patrimony,  ii.  455,  458,  460,  462,  469, 

474 

Patten,  Professor  Simon,  ii.  866 
Pattern-makers,  character  of,  1 08  ; 
object  to  amalgamation  and  form 
separate  union,  1 10  ;  division  among, 
in,  II  7>  nS;  touting  for  members, 
117;  rivalry  with  A.  S.  E.,  Il8; 


sectional  interests  of,  123,  129  ; 
federal  relations  of,  130,  132,  134; 
insist  on  time  work,  287  ;  strategic 
advantage  of,  ii.  479  ;  demarcation 
disputes  of,  509,  514 

Pea- picking,  ii.  544 

Pearl  Button  Makers,  395  ;  ii.  463,  475, 
498 

Peasant  proprietorship  at  Trade  Union 
Congress,  271 

Pease,  Sir  J.  W.,  232 

Pen  and  Pocket  Blade  Forgers,  395 

Pennsylvania,  election  of  executive  by 
districts,  47  ;  coal  trust  in,  448 

Penrhyn,  Lord,  244 

Pepys,  Samuel,  ii.  775 

Perceval,  H.  G.,  115 

Perkins,  F.,  231 

Permanent  Relief  Funds,  373  ;  ii.  529  ; 
literature  as  to,  366 

Perry,  A.  L.,  ii.  604,  606 

Peterborough,  pea-picking  at,  ii.  544 

Pickard,  B.,  262;  ii.  590 

Picketing,  ii.  719,  855 

Piecers,  wages  of,  105  ;  relation  of,  to 
spinners,  ii.  475,  497  ;  exclusion  of 
girls  from,  497  ;  excess  of,  ii.  735, 
759,  811.  See  Cotton  Operatives 

Piecework  forbidden  by  Stonemasons, 
77,  286,  297  ;  abolition  of,  desired 
by  Gasworkers,  147  ;  list  of  Trade 
Unions  which  object  to,  286  ;  list  of 
Trade  Unions  which  accept,  287  ;  as 
protection  against  sweating,  288  ;  as 
leading  to  sweating,  292 ;  explana- 
tion of  Trade  Union  posilion  with 
regard  to,  288-304 ;  effect  of,  on 
desire  for  Normal  Day,  328-334  ; 
associated  with  overtime,  346 ;  in- 
sisted on,  by  Boot  and  Shoe  Oper- 
atives, 398  ;  effect  of,  in  American 
boot  factories,  400  ;  objection  of  em- 
ployers to,  401  ;  mistaken  economic 
basis  of,  402  ;  effect  of,  on  machinery 
and  improvements,  413  ;  relation  of, 
to  sex  segregation,  ii.  501 

Lists,  antiquity  of,  283  ;  among 

Basketm  akers,  283  ;  among  Boot 
and  Shoe  Operatives,  188,  283,  314  ; 
among  Brushmakers,  283 ;  among 
Cabinetmakers,  301  ;  among  Com- 
positors, 283,  299,  314  ;  among 
Coopers,  283  ;  among  Cotton  Oper- 
atives, 195,  288,  312,  ii.  501  ;  among 
Hosiery  Workers,  ii.  502 ;  among 
Ironworkers,  283 ;  among  Tailors, 
279,  283 


Index 


921 


Place,  Francis,  9,  u,  299,  337,  402  ;  ii. 
542,  587,  638 

Plasterers,  working  rules  of,  175  ;  object 
to  piecework,  287 ;  Trade  Union 
membership  among,  287  ;  insist  on 
place  for  meals,  360  ;  ancient  gild  of, 
ii.  480 

Platelayers,  accidents  to,  376 

Platers.     See  Boilermakers 

Plater's  marker,  ii.  456 

Playfair,  Dr.  William,  ii.  454 

Lord,  ii.  585 

Plebiscite  in  France  strengthens  execu- 
tive, 26.  See  Referendum^  Initi- 
ative, Direct  Legislation 

Plimsoll,  S.,  364 

Plug  Riots,  the,  220 

Plumbers,  preference  for  rotation  of 
governing  branch,  17;  mode  of 
electing  executive,  17 ;  separate 
organisation  of  Scotch  and  English, 
83 ;  proposal  to  include,  in  A.  S.  E., 
112  ;  working  rules  of,  175  ; 
machinery  for  Collective  Bargaining 
among,  179 ;  desire  certificates  of 
proficiency,  252  ;  ii.  495  ;  object  to 
piecework,  287,  297  ;  Trade  Union 
membership  among,  287  ;  recruited 
from  plumbers'  mates  in  London,  ii. 
475>  4^9  ;  ancient  gild  of,  480 ;  de- 
marcation disputes  of,  509-518  ;  rule 
of,  as  to  working  for  customers,  ii.  579 

Pole,  W.,  ii.  469 

Politics,  exclusion  of,  4  ;  need  of  special 
organisation  for,  258-265  ;  cleavages 
in,  among  Trade  Unionists,  271  ; 
interest  in,  of  Trade  Unionists,  ii.  537 

Pollock,  Sir  Frederick,  366;  ii.  534,  853 

Poor  Law  Commissioners,  Report  of, 
163,  426,  750,  755 

Poor  Man's  Guardian,  the,  402 

Pope,  J.  Buckingham,  388 

Population,  influence  of  wages  on,  ii. 
612,617,632-643  ;  declining  increase 
of,  636 ;  deliberate  limitation  of, 
637-643  ;  in  Hearts  of  Oak  Friendly 
Society,  638  ;  in  Massachusetts,  641 

Porter,  G.  R. ,  448 

Portsmouth  Stonemasons,  77,  360 

Positivists,  the,  ii.  603,  618,  845 

Potter,  Edmund,  F.R.S.,  217,  220, 
308,  392  ;  ii.  565 

Potters*  Examiner,  the,  392,  393 

Potters  object  to  empty  hot  ovens,  358  ; 
vehemently  objected  to  machinery, 
392 ;  stint  among,  447 ;  revolted 
against  annual  hiring,  431 


Poverty,  influence  of,  on  birth-rate,  ii. 

637  ;  great  extent  of,  722,  766 
Preference  men,  121,  434 
President,    authority    of,    3,    4,    6,    7 ; 

chooses     committee,     8 ;      acts     in 

Collective  Bargaining,  179 
Preston  Carpenters,  5  ;  Cotton-weavers, 

315 

Price,  John  (of  Palmer  and  Co.),  ii.  513 

L.  L.  F.  R.,  205 

Prices,  relation  of  wages  to,  444 ;  ii. 
577,  869,  873 

Priestley  v.  Fowler,  366 

Primary  assembly,  in  America,  42  ;  the 
Trade  Union  branch  as,  102 

Prime  Cost,  ii.  665 

Primitive  Democracy,  vol.  i.  Part  I. 
ch.  i.  pp.  3-37 

Printer.     See  Compositors 

Printing,  change  of  custom  as  to 
electioneering,  80 ;  introduction  of 
stab  in,  299  ;  extras  in,  314  ;  intro- 
duction of  composing  machines  into, 
407  ;  wide  dispersion  of  industry  of, 
ii.  465  ;  introduction  of  women  into, 

499 

Priority,  position  and  purpose,  ii.  522 

Prison  labor,  ii.  787 

Profit-sharing,  reasons  why  Trade 
Unions  object  to,  ii.  551 

Profits,  theories  of,  ii.  604-653 ;  low 
rate  of,  on  watered  capital,  667  ; 
pools  of,  677,  806 ;  increased  by 
Common  Rules,  730  ;  not  interfered 
with  by  good  wages  or  short  hours, 
733  ;  and  Free  Trade,  863 

Progress,  definition  of,  ii.  703 

Progression,  ii.  498-495 

Progressive  Review,  the,  387 

Proportional  representation,  unsuited 
for  federal  bodies,  136;  especially  if 
they  act  as  umpires,  ii.  523 

Protection.     See  Free  Trade 

Protectionism,  local,  its  relation  to 
Trade  Unionism,  73-80  ;  resemblance 
of  Trade  Unionism  to  fiscal,  ii.  559 

Proxy  voting,  among  Northumberland 
Coalminers,  34  ;  in  Coalminers'  Con- 
ferences, 45  ;  at  Trade  Union  Con- 
gress, 277 

Prudential  Assurance  Company,  101 

Public  Health  Acts,  356;  ii.  771,  785,822 

QUEENSTOWN  Shipwrights,  75 
Quetelet,  ii.  637 

RAAIJMAKERS,  Charles,  160 


922 


Index 


Rae,  John,  324 

Railway  Servants,  constitution  of  union 
of,  46,  50  ;  national  character  of,  73 ; 
Irish  branches  of,  86,  87  ;  promote 
agitation  for  Employers'  Liability, 
369  ;  secure  special  clause,  370  ;  are 
compelled  to  contract  out,  372,  374  ; 
extreme  liability  of,  to  accidents,  376, 
378  ;  have  now  special  inspectors  for 
their  protection,  378  ;  irregularity  of 
work  among,  435  ;  desire  guaranteed 
minimum  of  weekly  earnings,  435  ; 
regulation  of  hours  of,  ii.  584,  594 

Railways,  irregular  employment  by, 
434 ;  overwhelming  strength  of,  ii. 
553?  691  ;  regulation  of  hours  on, 
5^5>  773  J  Parliamentary  monopoly 
of,  68 1  ;  fixing  of  minimum  wage  by, 
814;  application  of  arbitration  to,  814 

Springmakers,  ii.  564 

Rambert,  Eugene,  3,  7,  22 

Rational  Sick  and  Burial  Association, 
101 

Rattening,  213,  397 

Raymond,  Daniel,  ii.  618 

Razor  Hafters,  ii.  458,  459 

Redgrave,  349 

Red  Leaders,  ii.  509 

Reeves,  Hon.  W.  P.,  246;  ii.  814 

Referendum,  use  of,  among  Trade 
Unionists,  19  ;  idea  of,  derived  from 
Rittinghausen,  21  ;  results  of,  22  ; 
failure  of,  to  ensure  popular  control, 
23,  26,  31  ;  form  of,  among  North- 
umberland Coalminers,  33,  34 ; 
abandonment  of,  26 ;  logical  defect 
of,  6 1  ;  possible  sphere  for,  62 

Remission  of  rent,  effect  of,  ii.  762 

Renfrewshire  Coalminers,  ii.  587 

Rent,  nature  of,  ii.  643-645,  831 

Representative,  the  elected,  unknown 
in  early  Trade  Unions,  n,  19,  36; 
evolved  from  the  delegate,  37,  38,  44, 
47,  54,  63  ;  subject  to  the  caucus,  41 ; 
duties  of,  54;  must  be  specialised  and 
salaried,  65  ;  future  functions  of,  68 

Assembly,  absent  from  early  Trade 

Union  constitutions,  ii  ;  need  for, 
36 ;  form  of,  among  the  Cotton- 
spinners,  38 ;  among  the  Coal- 
miners,  43 ;  voting  at,  42,  45  ; 
superiority  of,  49 ;  difficulty  of 
obtaining,  53 ;  character  of,  66 ; 
future  of,  70 

Executive,  47  ;  working  of,  51 

Institutions,  vol.  i.  ch.  ii.  ;  as 

affected  by  federation,  136,  140 


Reserve  army,  economic  effects  of,  ii.  706 

Restriction  of  Numbers,  Devi.;e  of  the, 
ii.  560 ;  economic  effects  of,  704- 
714.  See  also  Population 

of  Output,  449  ;  ii.  708 

Retail  trade,  ii.  669,  684 

Rhodesia,  ii.  680 

Ricardo,  David,  ii.  604,  610,  622,  633, 
730,  869 

Richmond,  10 

Right  to  a  Trade,  the,  vol.  ii.  Part.  II. 
ch.  xi.  pp.  508-527,  809 

Riley,  H.  T.,  335;  ii.  498,  480,  459, 
5io,  511 

Ring -spinning,  introduction  of,  424  ; 
effect  on  mule-spinners,  427  ;  effect 
on  engineers,  ii.  733  ;  parasitic,  753 ; 
legal  regulation  of,  803 

Rings,  capitalist,  448  ;  ii.  577,  675, 
685,  689,  708 

Ritchie,  Professor  D.  G. ,  ii.  845 

Rittinghausen,  21 

Rivet-boy,  ii.  456,  481 

Rivetters.  See  Boot  and  Shoe  Opera- 
tives and  Boilermakers 

Roberts,  W.  H.,  366 

Rochdale  Cotton-spinners,  58 ;  Warpers, 
442 

Rodbertus,  324 

Rogers,  J.  E.  Thorold,  ii.  618,  727 

Romilly,  E.,  ii.  608 

Ropemakers,  of  Glasgow,  election 
customs,  6 

Rosebery,  the  Earl  of,  241,  242 

Rotation  of  office,  7  ;  in  old  friendly 
societies,  13 ;  of  governing  branch,  13, 
17 ;  in  the  Ancient  Order  of  Foresters, 
1 8  ;  among  Cotton  Operatives,  41  - 

Rotherhithe  Watermen,  437 

Rough-stuff  cutters,  418 

Rousiers,  Paul  de,  175,  434 

Royal  Commission  on  the  Aged  Poor 
(1893-95),  ;  385  ;  "•  529  5  °n  the 
Supply  of  Coal  (1873),  448  ;  on 
Children's  Employment,  285  ;  on 
Factories  (1837),  338,  355  ;  on 
Friendly  Societies,  101  ;  on  the 
Health  of  Towns,  355  ;  on  Labor 
(1891-95),  159,  207,  218,  219,  221, 
228,  230,  234,  291,  346,  358,  365, 393, 
434 ;  ii.  457,  531,  534,  5^3,  722,  770; 
on  the  Poor  Law  (1832-34),  162,  355, 
426;  on  Trade  Unions  (1867-69),  156, 
159,  167,  304,  305;  ii.  453,  461, 
553.  See  also  Select  Committee 

Prerogative,  use  of  the,  ii.  800 

Ruskin,  John,  ii.  618 


Index 


923 


SADDLERS,  336,  337,  352,  439 

Sailmakers,  rotation  of  office  among,  7  ; 
local  monopoly  among,  74,  75  ; 
machinery  of,  for  Collective  Bar- 
gaining, 179  ;  work  either  piece  or 
time,  287  ;  Trade  Union  membership 
among,  287  ;  apprenticeship  regula- 
tions of,  ii.  462 

Sailors,  political  desires  of,  252,  263  ; 
inability  of,  to  take  legal  proceedings, 
381  ;  exclusion  of,  from  Workmen's 
Compensation  Act,  388 

St.  Gall  adopts  Referendum,  19  ;  muni- 
cipal insurance  against  unemployment 
at,  160 

Salisbury,  Marquis  of,  390 

Samuda,  ii.  553 

Samuelson,  Sir  Bernhard,  205 

Sanger,  C.  P.,  ii.  454,  457,  473 

Sanitation  and  Safety  of  the  workplace, 
vol.  i.  Part  II.  ch.  vii.  pp.  354-391  ; 
modernness  of  demand  for,  355  ;  Trade 
Union  policy  in,  361,  385 ;  Home 
Work  involves  lowering  of,  ii.  541  ; 
not  now  abandoned  to  Supply  and 
Demand,  583,  584 

Saturday  half-holiday,  352 

Sauerbeck,  ii.  577 

Saunders,  W. ,  ii.  469 

Saving,  influences  affecting,  ii.  621- 
627 

Savvsmiths,  395 

Sawyers,  ii.  479,  509 

Scab,  description  of,  207,  215 

Schaeffle,  Albert,  324 

Schanz,  G.,  ii.  455 

Schloss,  D.  F.,  285,  297 

Schmoller,  Professor  Gustav,    414  ;   ii. 

455»  754 

Schoenhof,  J.,  401  ;  ii.  726 

School  teachers,  ii.  791,  826 

Schulze-Gaevernitz,  Dr.  G.  von,  29, 
223,  289 

Schwabe,  ii.  637 

Schwiedland,  Dr.  Eugen,  414 

Scotland,  independence  of  Trade  Unions 
in,  82  ;  character  of  Trade  Unionism 
in,  82,  83 

Scottish  Bakers,  287 ;  Boilermakers, 
82  ;  Carpenters,  340  ;  Compositors, 
287  ;  Cotton-weavers,  10  ;  ii.  543  ; 
Handloom  Weavers,  9 ;  Ironfounders, 
430 ;  Shoemakers,  ii.  539 ;  Stone- 
masons, 287  ;  Tailors,  286  ;  ii.  540 

Scythe  Grinders,  440,  442  ;  ii.  459 

Seaports,  monopoly  spirit  strong  in,  73  ; 
demarcation  disputes  in,  ii.  509 


Secrecy,  caused  by  prosecutions,  9,  10 

Secretary,  original  subordination  of,  6  ; 
elected  by  whole  society,  14  ;  special- 
isation and  permanence  of  tenure  of, 
X5>  4°j  5°  5  subjected  to  competitive 
examination,  16  ;  chooses  committee, 
8  ;  acts  in  Collective  Bargaining,  179 

Sectional  unions,  117 

Seeley,  Sir  John,  ii.  847 

Seguier,  ii.  566 

Select  Committee  on  Artisans  and 
Machinery  (1824),  10,  II,  319,  355  ; 
ii.  453;  on  Climbing  Boys  (1817), 
363  ;  on  the  Coal  Trade  (1800,  1829, 
and  1830),  448  ;  on  Combinations  of 
Workmen  (1825),  8,  355,  420 ;  ii. 
453  ;  on  Conditions  of  Government 
Contracts  (1897),  ii.  776  ;  on  the 
Cotton  Cloth  Factories  Act  (1889), 
359;  on  Employers'  Liability  (1887), 
366  376,  380  ;  on  National  Provi- 
dent Insurance  (1885),  Ir4  >  on  Peti- 
tions of  Artisans  (1811),  249;  ii. 
679 ;  on  Railway  and  Canal  Bills 
(1853),  ii.  582  ;  on  the  Sweating 
System  (1887-1891),  364  ;  ii.  543, 
548,  588,  589,  655,  765,  771,  772  ;  on 
Trade  Unions  (1838),  ii.  453  ;  on 
the  Woollen  Manufacture  (1806),  ii. 
4^5>  679.  See  also  Royal  Commis- 
sion 

Selection  of  the  Fittest,  definition  of, 
ii.  703 

Senior,  Nassau,  328;  ii.  485,  617,  623, 
635,  653,  868 

Servitor,  ii.  490 

Sewage  farms,  ii.  788 

Sewing  machine,  introduction  of,  to 
bootmaking,  393,  418 

Sexual  relationships,  economic  influence 
of,  ii.  750 

Shaftesbury,  Earl  of,  364,  440 ;  ii.  763 

Shand,  Lord,  ii.  590 

Shearmen,  ii.  459 

Sheffield  Iris,  the,  336 

Sheffield,  apprenticeship  in,  ii.  458,  463, 
478  ;  cutlery  trades  in,  179,  263,  343, 
395,  434 ;  ii.  458,  463,  478,  800 ; 
effect  of  Trade  Unionism  in,  ii.  614  ; 
outwork  in,  ii.  543  ;  rattening  and 
violence  in,  213 ;  Britannia  Metal 
Smiths,  ii.  458  ;  Edge  Tool  Forgers, 
ii.  459  ;  File  Cutters,  286,  395  ;  File 
Forgers,  395  ;  Pen  and  Pocket  Blade 
Forgers,  395  ;  Razor  Grinders,  ii.  459 ; 
Razor  Hafters,  ii.  459  ;  Saw  Smiths, 
395  >  Scythe  Grinders,  440,  442  ;  ii. 


924 


Index 


458  ;  Table  Blade  Forgers,  395  ; 
Tailors,  336  ;  Wool  Shear  Benders, 
439  ;  Wool  Shear  Grinders,  ii.  459 

Shipwrights,  of  Liverpool,  drinking 
rules,  5  >  compulsory  office  among, 
7 ;  local  monopolies  of,  73,  75 ; 
congresses  of,  74  >  formation  of 
Associated  Shipwrights'  Society,  74  ; 
absorption  of  local  societies,  74,  76 ; 
spreading  from  Glasgow  Society  of, 
82  ;  irregularities  of  Irish  branches, 
86 ;  divergence  of  interest  between 
joiners  and,  130;  in  federal  union 
with  other  trades,  132  ;  introduction 
of  out  of  work  pay  among,  164  ; 
Trade  Union  membership  among, 
287  ;  work  either  piece  or  time,  287  ; 
desire  of,  for  Normal  Day,  333,  341  ; 
hours  of  labor  of,  341  ;  objection  of, 
to  overtime,  341,  439;  prohibit  en- 
grossing of  work,  439  ;  demarcation 
disputes  of,  ii.  509-518 

Shoe  and  Leather  Record,  the,  78,  188, 
189,  191,  192,  322,  398,  400;  ii.  550 

Shoemakers  (hand),  of  Edinburgh,  rules 
as  to  keymasters,  6  ;  separate  organ- 
isation of  Scotch  and  English,  83  ; 
description  of  scab,  207  ;  indifference 
of,  to  Normal  Day,  342  ;  effect  of 
home  work  among,  ii.  541  ;  enlight- 
ened policy  towards  machinery,  418  ; 
strict  maintenance  of  Standard  of 
Life  by,  419 ;  ancient  demarcation 
cases  among,  ii.  510,  511.  See  Boot 
and  Shoe  Operatives 

Shop  assistants,  ii.  804 

Shop  bargain,  173,  279,  302 

Shops,  psychology  of  expensive,  ii.  670 

Short  time,  policy  of,  448 

Shot-firing,  proposed  restriction  of,  126 

Sick  benefit,  administered  by  branch  as 
jury,  TOO  ;  variation  of,  in  different 
societies,  101  ;  an  element  in  Trade 
Union  insurance,  152;  causes  objec- 
tion to  employers'  benefit  societies. 
ii.  551  ;  future  of,  826 

Sidgwick,  Professor  H.,  ii.  650,  651, 
652,  800 

Sigismund,  the  Emperor,  ii.  565 

Silk-dressers,  ii.  490,  493 

Hatters.     See  Hatters 

Throwers,  ii.  587 

— —  Weavers,  434  ;  ii.  543,  760 

Silver  engraving,  women  attempt,  ii. 
498  ;  hours  in,  800 

Sismondi,  J.  C.  L.  S.  de,  ii.  568 

Six  Days'  Custom,  436 


Skinners,  ii.  460 

Slaters,  working  rules  of,  175  ;  pro- 
gression among,  ii.  489 ;  protest 
against  Bricklayers'  encroachments, 

515 

Slaves,  trade  in,  ii.  569  ;  enfranchise- 
ment of,  569 ;  economic  effect  of, 
751,  778,  868 

Sliding  Scale,  in  iron  trade,  205,  211, 
231-234,  237  ;  in  South  Wales  coal- 
mining, 209,  237 ;  in  Northumber- 
land and  Durham,  234  ;  compulsory 
nature  of,  209,  216 ;  inconsistent 
with  Trade  Union  policy  on  over- 
production, 446  ;  disastrous  character 
of,  ii.  576,  587 

Small  masters,  Trade  Union  objection 
to,  ii.  546 

Smart,  Professor  W.,  445  ;  ii.  618,  626, 
648,  673 

Smith,  Adam,  337,  356,  357  ;  ii.  454, 
481,  569,  617,  623,  624,  626,  656, 
695,  869 

Assheton,  375 

E.  J.,  ii.  578,  665 

Erasmus  P.,  ii.  618 

—  H.  Llewellyn,  433  ;  ii.  589 

Smiths,  character  of,  108,  123  ;  retain 
sectional  unions,  no;  rivalry  with 
A.  S.  E.,  118;  federal  relations  of, 
129,  132,  134;  use  of  Strike  in 
Detail  by,  168  ;  work  either  piece  or 
time,  287  ;  relations  of,  to  strikers, 
290,  ii.  480  ;  ancient  gild  of,  480  ; 
demarcation  disputes  of,  509.  See 
Engineers 

Smoking  allowed  at  members'  meet- 
ings* 5  ;  forbidden,  6 

Smooting,  439 

Socialism  among  Trade  Unionists,  271  ; 
at  Trade  Union  Congress,  271  ;  ob- 
jection to  piecework  ascribed  to, 
282  ;  economic  basis  of,  402  ;  influ- 
ence of,  with  regard  to  admission  of 
women,  ii.  5°°  >  by  Trade  Option, 
536  ;  relation  of  Trade  Unionists  to, 
539,  598,  832 

Social  Science,  National  Association 
for  the  Promotion  of,  76,  153,  169, 
217,  220,  308,  337,  340,  359,  392, 
393,  401,  403,  432;  ii.  544,  564,  565 

Sombart,  Prof.  Werner,  414 

Somerset  Coalminers,  126;  cloth 
manufacture,  ii.  764 

South  African  coal,  ii.  741 

Australia,    Conciliation    Act    of, 

246;  ii.  815 


Index 


925 


South  Wales  Coalminers,  126,  209, 
237,  286,  374 ;  ii.  577  5  Tinplate 
Workers,  286 

Metropolitan  Gas  Works,  ii.  777 

Sovereignty,  ii.  845 

Spanish  and  Morocco  Leather  Finishers' 
Society,  167  ;  ii.  460 

Specialisation,  in  the  art  of  govern- 
ment, 59,  64;  in  cotton  manufac- 
ture, 105,  125  ;  in  engineering,  107  ; 
ii.  471  ;  in  handicrafts,  419 ;  be- 
tween the  sexes,  ii.  501,  507  ;  in 
shipbuilding,  509,  516 

Speeding  up  in  cotton-mills  in  boot  and 
shoe  factories,  399 ;  in  engineering 
works,  428 

Spencer,  Herbert,  ii.  781 

Spens,  W.  C.,366 

Spindle  and  Flyer  Makers,  287 

Spitalfields  Silk-weavers,  ii.  543 

Spring  Knife  Grinders,  163 

Stafford  Boot  Trade  Board,  187 

Staffordshire  Ironworkers,  233,  234  ; 
Potters,  286,  316,  358,  431  ;  Oven- 
men,  358 

Staircasing,  284 

Standard  of  Life,  ii.  693-700 

Oil  Company,  ii.  709 

Rate,  vol.  i.  Part  I.  ch.  v. 

pp.  279-323  ;  relation  of,  to  Normal 
Day,  330;  relation  of  Machinery  to, 
405  ;  effect  of,  on  sex  competition, 
ii.  498-507  ;  application  of,  to  de- 
marcation disputes,  524  ;  adverse  in- 
fluence of  small  masters  on,  547 ; 
relation  of  profit  sharing  to,  551  ; 
effect  of,  as  a  bulwark,  701  ;  in  caus- 
ing selection  of  the  fittest,  718 

State  Insurance,  390 ;  ii.  529,  827 

Statesman's  Manual,  42 

Steam  Engine  Makers,  drinking  rules, 
5 ;  rotation  of  office  among,  7 ; 
rotation  of  governing  branch  among, 
13  ;  delegate  meetings  of,  19  ;  foreign 
branches  of,  81  ;  object  to  amalga- 
mation, no;  proposal  to  increase 
superannuation  funds,  116;  rivalry 
with  other  engineers'  unions,  117; 
federal  relations  of,  132;  treaty  of, 
with  Cardiff  Boilermakers,  ii.  520. 
See  Engineers 

Steel  Smelters,  national  society  develop- 
ing from  Glasgow,  82  ;  insist  on 
piecework,  286  ;  membership  of, 
286  ;  system  of  progression  among, 
ii.  490  ;  term  of  service  among,  493  ; 
objection  of,  to  restriction  on  em- 


ployer's selection,  494;  earnings  of, 
582 

Stephan,  H.,  324 

Stephen,  Leslie,  ii.  606 

Stephens,  W.  Walker,  ii.  566 

Stephenson,  Robert,  ii.  581 

Stimson,  F.  G.,  253 

F.  J.,  ii.  86 1 

Stint,  447 

Stirling,  James,  159,  224,  ii.  611,  612, 
613,  614,  621,  622,  653,  690,  841 

Stocking-frame  workers.  See  Hosiery 
Workers 

Stocks  of  coal,  447 

Stone  Carvers,  360 

Stonemasons,  long  stay  of  head  office 
in  London,  17 ;  delegate  meetings 
of,  19 ;  adopt  Referendum,  21  ;  ex- 
perience of  Direct  Legislation  among, 
22,  24  ;  declare  rules  unalterable, 
25  ;  local  monopoly  among,  75,  77  ; 
prohibition  of  importation  of  worked 
stone  by,  77  ;  working  rules  of,  77, 
98  ;  separate  organisation  of  Scotch 
and  English,  83  ;  irregularities  of 
Irish  branches  of,  84  ;  centralisation 
of  funds  among,  91  ;  spasmodic  local 
strikes  among,  98  ;  local  autonomy 
of  branches  among,  98  ;  federal  re- 
lations of,  134 ;  rule  as  to  provision  of 
dinner  by  employers,  98,  366  ;  ex- 
haustion of  funds  of,  155  ;  working 
rules  of,  175,  360 ;  machinery  for 
Collective  Bargaining  among,  180  ; 
political  desires  of,  264 ;  Standard 
Rate  of,  279,  323  ;  differentiation  of 
work  among,  284  ;  forbid  piecework, 
287,  288,  298  ;  Trade  Union  'mem- 
bership among,  287  ;  object  to  chas- 
ing, 304  ;  desire  of,  for  Normal  Day, 
340,  351  ;  hours  of  labor  of,  340, 
352  ;  start  Nine  Hours'  Movement, 
340,  352  ;  insist  on  place  for  dinner, 
360  ;  apprenticeship  regulations 
among,  ii.  460,  463,  473,  478  ; 
ancient  gild  of,  480  ;  wages  of,  873 

Strikes  begun  by  single  branches  in 
building  trades,  97 ;  approval  of 
council  required  among  Carpenters, 
99 ;  spasmodic  local,  98 ;  largely 
non-unionist  in  origin,  178;  rendered 
less  frequent  by  Trade  Unionism, 
221  ;  outbreak  of,  about  demarca- 
tion, ii.  509,  513  ;  probable  public 
interference  to  prevent,  813 

Strike  in  Detail,  description  of,  169  ; 
among  the  Tapesizers,  107  ;  among 


926 


Index 


the  Leather  Finishers,  167  ;  among 
the  Smiths,  168  ;  among  the  Flint 
Glass  Makers,  169  ;  drawbacks  of, 
171 

Strikers  unite  with  Smiths,  129  ;  ob- 
tain piecework  rate,  290  ;  relation  of, 
to  Smiths,  ii.  480  ;  progression  of,  490 

Stuff- pressers,  215  ;  ii.  463,  478 

Stussi,  24 

Subcontracting  forbidden  in  building 
contracts,  298 

Sugar  bounties,  ii.  767,  779 

Superannuation  benefit,  152  ;  insecure, 
:55>  J57  »  causes  objection  to  em- 
ployers' benefit  societies,  ii.  551 

Supply  and  Demand,  Doctrine  of,  ii. 
562,  572-584,  593-599,  810 

Sweated  trades,  inadequacy  of  factory 
legislation  for,  364  ;  irregularity  of 
employment  in,  433  ;  inevitability  of 
Individual  Bargaining  in,  435  ;  Trade 
Union  objection  to  Home  Work  in, 
"•  539  >  result  of  Supply  and  De- 
mand in,  589  ;  parasitic  nature  of, 
749-766;  future  of,  817 

Switzerland,  the  Landesgemeinden  of, 
3,  7,  22 ;  election  of  executive  com- 
mittee by  districts,  47  ;  sale  of  offices 
in,  7,  22  ;  small  results  of  the  Initi- 
ative, 24  ;  obedience  to  popular  will 
in,  68  ;  education  and  child-labor  in, 
ii.  769 

Symes,  Rev.  J.  E.,  ii.  618 

TABLE  Blade  Forgers,  395 

Tailors,  militant  organisation  of,  9  > 
separate  organisation  of  Scotch  and 
English,  83,  120;  irregularities  of 
Irish  branches  of,  85  ;  large  number 
of  branches  in  Ireland,  87  ;  accusa- 
tions of  blacklegging  among,  120  ; 
contagious  disease  benefit  among, 
152;  political  objects  of,  252,  263; 
extreme  dispersion  of,  264  ;  insist  on 
piecework,  286  ;  Trade  Union  mem- 
bership of,  286  ;  antiquity  of  piece- 
work lists,  283 ;  do  not  object  to 
extra  payment,  279 ;  plurality  of 
standard  rates  among  Scottish,  322  ; 
hours  of  labor  of,  336,  352,  356  ;  ii. 
800  ;  desire  of,  for  Normal  Day,  336  ; 
action  of,  against  underground  work- 
shops, 359  ;  insanitary  conditions  of, 
358 ;  degeneration  of  unorganised 
sections  of,  416  ;  strong  feeling 
against  unemployment,  430 ;  influ- 
ence of  outwork  among,  ii.  544 


Tallyman,  tally  system,  ii.  654,  674 

Tangye.and  Company,  ii.  690 

Tantum,  447 

Tapesizers,  wages  of,  105  ;  type  of 
Trade  Unionism  required  by,  106 ; 
federal  relations  of,  123  ;  Strike  in 
Detail  employed  by,  107  ;  use  of  out 
of  work  pay  by,  165  ;  refuse  to  work 
with  non-unionists,  215;  strategic 
position  of,  ii.  478 

Task  work  forbidden  among  Boiler- 
makers, 300 

Tattersall,  W.,  201 

Taussig,  Professor  F.  W.,  ii.  604,  618, 
650 

Taxation,  ii.  871 

Team  system,  399-404  ;  ii.  483 

Technical  education,  apprenticeship  as, 
ii.  476  ;  must  be  paid  by  community, 
481 ;  connection  of,  with  Living  Wage, 
595  ;  decay  of,  in  London,  770  ;  real 
object  of,  829 

Temperton  v.  Russell,  ii.  859 

Tenement  factory,  ii.  539 

Ten  Hours'  Day  of  Cotton  Operatives, 
250,  338  ;  ii.  565  ;  of  Engineers,  336, 
351,  352  ;  of  Building  Trades,  336, 
352;  of  Tailors,  336,  351 

Tenant  right,  ii.  567 

Tenters,  children  employed  by  Cotton- 
weavers  as,  105;  ii.  Si  I  ;  assistants 
to  Calico  Printers,  481 

Textile  Factory  Workers'  Association, 
the  United,  124,  251,  258  ;  objects 
to  arbitration,  244  ;  organisation  of, 
as  political  machine,  258-260  ;  con- 
sults experts,  268  ;  influence  of,  in 
Trade  Union  Congress,  278 ;  tem- 
porarily suspended,  260 

Theatres,   employment  of  children  in, 

364 
Thomas,  D.  A.,  448 

E.,  226 

Thompson,  Professor  R.  E.,  ii.  866 

William,  403  ;  ii.  618 

Thorneycroft's  Scale,  232 

Thornton,  W.  T.,   304;  ii.  605,   618, 

620,  628,  646 

Three  shifts  objected  to,  412 
Tilers,  ii.  515 
Times,  the,  64,  293,  448;  ii.  534,  732, 

804 

Timework.     See  Piecework 
Tinplate  Workers,  286,   300,   432  ;  ii 

509,  517 

Tomn,  Lilian,  19 
Toolmakers,  ill.     See  Engineers 


Index 


927 


Torrens,  Robert,  ii.  696 
Toyn,  Joseph,  229 

Trade  Unionism  and  Democracy,  vol. 
ii.  Part  III.  ch.  iv.  pp.  807-847 

difficulty    of    defining    a,     104. 

See  also  Demarcation 

marks,  ii.  685 

Union    Congress,    character    and 

activities  of,  265-278  ;  change  in  con- 
stitution of,  276  ;  policy  of,  in  regard 
to  Employers'  Liability,  369,  382 

Trade  Unionist,  the,  ill 

Trades  Councils,  character  and  activities 

of,  265-278  ;  ii.  838 
Tramway  men,  public  sympathy  with, 

ii.  535  ;  horses,  692,  751 
Transport  workers,  disorganisation  of, 

121.     See  Railway  Servants 
Travelling  benefit,  variety  of  out  of  work 

pay,  153  ;   among  Woolcombers  and 

Weavers,  162 ;  described  by  Poor  Law 

Commissioner,  162 
Treasurer  of  early  clubs  the  publican, 

6  ;  superseded  by  the  box  with  three 

locks,  6 

Trevelyan,  C.  P.,  19 
Trow,  Edward,  205,  211 
Truck,  objected  to,  263,  271,  317 

Act  of  1896,  exemption  of  iron- 
workers from,  21 1 ;  suggested  applica- 
tion of,  to  employers'  benefit  societies, 
373 ;  dislike  of,  ii.  799 

Trusts,  coal,  448 

Tunstill,  William,  ii.  534 

Turgot,  A.,  ii.  566,  569 

Turners,  108.     See  Engineers 

Turnway  societies,  437 

Twisters,  wages  of,  105  ;  type  of  Trade 
Unionism  required  by,  105  ;  federal 
relations  of,  123  ;  patrimony  among, 
ii.  462  ;  exclusion  of  women  by,  498 

Tyne,  Tyneside.     See  Newcastle 

Typographical  Association.  See  Com- 
positors 

UMPIRE,  difficulties  of,  in  boot  trade, 

1 88,  189  ;  usually  a  large  employer, 

189,  231,  235  ;  procedure  before  an, 
223,   229,    242  ;   assumption  of  the, 
230 ;    unique   case   of  workman   as, 
231  ;    gratuitous    services    of,    231  ; 
statesman  or  lawyer  as,  231 ;  politician 
or  clergyman  objected  to,  190,  240  ; 
services  of  Mr.  T.  Burt  as,  ii.  511 

Underground  workshops,  359 
Unemployable,  the,  ii.  784 
Unemployment,    provision    of    Dublin 


Coopers  against,  75  >  benefits  insuring 
against,  153  ;  municipal  insurance 
against,  160;  fundamental  position  of, 
in  Trade  Union  Mutual  Insurance, 
161  ;  relation  of,  to  hours  of  labor, 
341  ;  regularity  of,  in  sweated  trades, 
433  >  n°t  prevented  by  yearly  hirings, 
432 ;  French  arrangements  against, 
437>  438  5  not  obviated  by  reduction 
of  wage,  445  ;  inevitability  of,  784  ; 
future  provision  for,  829 ;  suggested 
trade  classes  for,  830 

Unhealthy  trades,  cause  degradation  of 
workers,  357  ;  not  systematically 
regulated  by  Parliament,  363 

Unit  of  government,  vol.  i.  Part  I.  ch. 
iii.  ;  original  local  society,  73 ;  as 
affected  by  federation,  134,  140 

United  States,  labor  laws  unconstitu- 
tional in,  253.  See  also  America 

Unskilled  labor,  inability  of,  to  raise 
wages,  ii.  757 

Upholsterers,  ii.  467,  509,  516 

Uri,  3 

Utility,  marginal,  determines  value  and 
wages,  ii.  645 

VEND,  limitation  of  the,  448 
Verein  fur  sociale  Politik,  414 
Vested    interests,    conception     of,    in 
demarcation      disputes,      ii.       514 ; 
Doctrine  of,  ii.  562-572,  595 
Victim  pay,  153 
Victoria,  factory  act  of,  246  ;  ii.   488, 

770,  776 
Villerme,  ii.  637 
Vincent,  J.  M.,  3,  47 
Violence,  crimes  of,  213,  249  ;  iL  853 
Voting,  accumulative  system  of,  among 
Coalminers,    45 ;    at    Trade    Union 
Congress,  277  ;    little   used  by  early 
Trade  Unions,  7 ;   method  of,  among 
London    Brushmakers,    14 ;    among 
Northumberland  Coalminers,  34,  45  ; 
ballot  required  before  strike,  41,  62  ; 
controlled  by  caucus,  41  ;   separated 
from   discussion,   33  ;    system  of,  in 
federations,   136;  ii.   523.     See  also 
Direct  Legislation,  Initiative,  Refer- 
endum 

WAGE-EARNING  class,  aggregate  income 

of,  445  ;  ii.  781 
Wage  Fund,  theory  of  the,  ii.  603-632  ; 

literature  as  to,  604  ;  dissenters  from, 

618 
Wages,  relation  of,  to  prices,  444  ;  ii. 


928 


Index 


577 ;  influences  affecting,  ii.  603- 
653  ;  in  different  countries,  695  ; 
small  effect  of,  on  cost  of  production, 
733  ;  of  Beamers,  105  ;  of  Boiler- 
makers, ii.  593  ;  of  Boot  and  Shoe 
Operatives,  400,  406  ;  of  Cardroom 
Operatives,  105  ;  of  Carpenters,  321; 
of  Chain  and  Nail  Workers,  ii.  754  ; 
of  Cotton  Operatives,  105;  of  Dockers, 
ii.  588,  694  ;  of  Domestic  Servants, 
ii.  674  ;  of  Government  Employees, 
ii.  555  ;  of  Overlookers,  105  ;  of 
Papermakers,  421  ;  of  Piecers,  105  ; 
of  Ring-spinners,  424  ;  of  Tapesizers, 
105  ;  of  Tenters,  105  ;  of  Twisters, 
105  ;  of  Warpers,  105  ;  of  Women, 
ii.  495-507.  See  also  under  particular 
trades,  and  Piecework  and  Standard 
Rate 

Walker,  Amasa,  ii.  618 

—  F.  A.,  355  ;  ii.  604,  607,  618,  649 

Walking  time,  175,  313 

Wallace,  G.  H.,  366 

Wallas,  Graham,  402  ;  ii.  542 

Wanderjahre,  ii.  455 

Warnham  v.  Stone,  ii.  858 

Warpers,  wages  of,  105  ;  cast  lots  for 
jobs,  442  ;  patrimony  among,  ii.  460. 
See  Cotton  Operatives 

Washington,  George,  ii.  841 

Watchmaking,  ii.  760 

Waterford  Compositors,  85 

Watermen,  excluded  from  Workmen's 
Compensation  Act,  389  ;  turnway 
societies  of,  437 

Waterworks,  monopoly  of,  ii.  569,  582 
736 

Watson,  Dr.  R.  Spence,  231,  233,  235, 

239,  240 
Reuben,  114 

Wayland,  Dr.,  ii.  618 

Weavers.  See  Handloom  Weavers, 
Cotton  Weavers,  Silk  Weavers, 
Carpet  Weavers 

Weekly  pays,  431 

Weiller,  Julien,  223 

Westphalia,  coal  trust  in,  448 

Wheat,  price  of,  ii.  876 

Wheel-chargemen,    ii.   490,   493,    494, 

495 
—  rent,  316  ;   ii.  539 

Whewell,  ii.  759 

Whitesmiths,  ii.  486 

Whitwell,  205,  232 

Whitworth's  Engineering  Works  (Man- 
chester), 104 

Wilkie,  Alexander,  82,  164  ;  ii.  518 


Wilkinson,  T.,  201,  409 

Rev.  J.  Frome,  89,  101  ;  ii. 

827 

Wilson,  Woodrow,  42,  59 

Wiltshire  cloth  manufacture,  ii.  764 

Window  Glass  Workers,  444 

Wire-drawers,  286 

weavers,  ii.  564 

Wise,  B.  R.,  ii.  692,  865 

Wolff,  H.  W.,  366 

Wolverhampton  Tinplate  Workers,  300 

Women,  ring-spinners  admitted  to  Card- 
room  Operatives'  Union,  424;  in  boot 
factories  admitted  to  National  Union 
of  Boot  and  Shoe  Operatives,  425  ; 
in  clothing  factories,  not  organised, 
427  ;  entrance  of,  to  trades,  ii.  495-507 ; 
change  of  policy  with  regard  to,  497  ; 
application  of  Standard  Rate  to,  500 ; 
policy  of  segregation,  501-507  ;  con- 
dition of,  in  Home  Work  trades,  540 ; 
pea- pickers,  544 ;  effect  of  Supply  and 
Demand  on,  582  ;  limitation  of  hours 
of,  583  ;  deliberate  restriction  of 
family  by,  638  ;  Standard  of  Life  of, 
698 ;  amenities  of  the  factory  for, 
715 ;  ill-health  of,  723 ;  bad  condition 
of,  in  laundries,  727  ;  often  parasitic- 
ally  employed,  749  -  766  ;  having 
children  to  attend  to,  783  ;  effect  of 
National  Minimum  on,  791  ;  long 
hours  of,  800 

Woods,  Samuel,  262  ;  ii.  589 

Wood  turners,  ii.  486 

Wool  -  combers,  travelling  benefit  of, 
162  ;  strike  of,  at  Kendal,  162 

Shear  Benders,  439 

Shear  Grinders,  ii.  459 

staplers,  rules  of  order  among,  4  ; 

compulsory  office  among,  7  ;  early 
rules  of,  II  ;  hierarchy  of  authorities 
among,  12  ;  apprenticeship  among, 
ii.  462  ;  patrimony  among,  460 

Worcestershire  Ironworkers,  234 

Worked  stone,  rule  against  importation 
of,  77 

Working  Rules  of  building  trades,  97, 
I75>  3°4)  3I3>  36°?  442  ;  conflicts 
between,  98  ;  against  importation  of 
worked  stone,  77  ;  requiring  dinner 
to  be  provided,  98 ;  miscellaneous 
provisions  of,  175,  313,  360  ;  enforced 
by  law,  178  ;  grinding  money,  175, 
313;  walking  time,  175,313;  lodging 
money,  313  ;  black  or  dirty  money, 
313  ;  shelter  against  rain,  360  ;  place 
for  dinner,  360  ;  unalterable  for  long 


Index 


929 


term,     442 ;     against    working    for 
private  customer,  ii.  580 
Workmen's  Compensation  Act  of  1897, 

387-391 
Wright,  Carroll  D.,  223 

Sir  Thomas,  186,  404 

R.  S.,ii.  857 

YEARLY  bond,  431,  432 


Yorkshire  Coalminers,  43,  45,  53,  212, 
215,  229,  374;  Flint  Glass  Makers, 
280;  Glass  Bottle  Makers,  286,  316, 
447  ;  Stuff-pressers,  ii.  463;  Woollen 
Workers,  768;  politics  of  Trade 
Unionists  of,  271 

Younger,  R.  F.,  366 

ZURICH,  Initiative  in,  24 


THE    END 


VOL.  II 


Printed  by  R.  &  R.  CI.AKK,  LIMITED,  Edinburgh, 


BY  THE    SAME   AUTHORS. 
THE   HISTORY  OF  TRADE   UNIONISM 

Price  iSs. 

PROBLEMS  OF  MODERN  INDUSTRY 

Price  is.  6d. 
LONDON  :  LONGMANS,  GREEN  AND  CO. 


THE  CASE  FOR  THE  FACTORY  ACTS 

Edited  by  Mrs.  SIDNEY  WEBB,  with  a  Preface  by  Mrs.  HUMPHRY  WARD. 

Price  is. 

LABOR  IN  THE  LONGEST  REIGN 
(1837-1897) 

By  SIDNEY  WEBB.     Price  is. 
LONDON:  GRANT  RICHARDS. 


SOCIALISM  IN  ENGLAND 

By  SIDNEY  WEBB.    Price  2s.  6d. 

THE  LONDON  PROGRAMME 

By  SIDNEY  WEBB.    Price  2s.  6d. 

THE  CO-OPERATIVE  MOVEMENT  IN  GREAT 
BRITAIN 

By  BEATRICE  POTTER  (Mrs.  Sidney  Webb).     Price  is.  6d. 
LONDON:  SONNENSCHEIN  AND  CO. 

THE   EIGHT  HOURS  DAY 

By  SIDNEY  WEBB  and  HAROLD  Cox.    Price  is. 
LONDON  :  WALTER  SCOTT. 

DER   SOCIALISMUS   IN  ENGLAND 

GESCHILDERT  VON  ENGLISCHEN  SOCIALISTEN. 
Herausgegeben  von  SIDNEY  WEBB 

GOTTINGEN  :  VANDENHOEK  UND  RUPRECHT. 


HD  Passfield,  Sidney  James 

6664.  Webb,  baron 
P33  Industrial  democracy 

1902  New.ed. 


PLEASE  DO  NOT  REMOVE 
CARDS  OR  SLIPS  FROM  THIS  POCKET 

UNIVERSITY  OF  TORONTO  LIBRARY