Skip to main content

Full text of "The influence of protection on agriculture in Germany"

See other formats


\^ 


GIFT   OF 


•Xt&  ^  & 


PRICE    ONE    PENNY 


if 


The 


Influence  of  Protec 


on 


Agriculture  in  Germany 


Publi.hed  by  CASSELL  AND  COMPANY,  LTD., 

La  Belle  Sauvage,  Ludgate  Hill,  London,  E.C., 
FOR   THE 

COBDEN  CLUB,  Caxton  House,  Westminster,  S.W. 

1910 


The 

Influence  of  Protection 

on  Agriculture  in 

Germany 


Published   by   CASSELL  &  COMPANY,    LTD., 

La  Belle  Sauvage,    Ludgate   Hill,  London,  E.G., 

FOR    THE 

GOBDEN  CLUB,  Gaxton  House,  Westminster,  S.W. 

1910 


ttf2 

3:6 


>    . 


The  Influence  of  Protection  on 
Agriculture  in  Germany 

Nothing  in  German  political  history  of  to-day  has 
been  more  remarkable  than  the  results  of  the  recent 
by-elections  to  the  Reichstag,  at  Usedom-Wollin  and 
Friedberg-Biidingen.  Both  are  essentially  agrarian  con- 
stituencies, and  the  latter  specially  was  represented  for 
seventeen  years  by  one  of  the  chief  Agrarian  leaders  in 
Germany,  Count  Oriola,  a  pillar  of  the  formidable  Union 
of  Farmers,  the  organisation  of  Prussian  and  other 
Junkers.  Yet  in  both  the  Agrarian  candidates  have  sus- 
tained a  crushing  defeat,  and  that  at  the  hands  of  the 
Social  Democrats.  Seeing  that  the  latter  had  at  no  time 
in  the  course  of  their  previous  history  been  able  to  obtain 
anything  like  a  solid  footing  in  the  agricultural  districts, 
and  at  the  general  election  of  1907  lost  enormously  pre- 
cisely in  the  rural  and  semi-rural  constituencies,  the  present 
remarkable  swing  of  political  opinion  among  the  agricul- 
tural population  cannot  but  be  regarded  as  a  symptom 
of  profound  unrest,  due  to  some  formidable  cause.  A 
peasant  population,  which  in  Germany,  as  elsewhere,  is 
not  only  dominated  by  the  squire  and  parson,  but  by  the 
whole  chain  of  traditions  and  conceptions  handed  down 
from  centuries  before,  is  not  easily  moved  even  on  the 
road  which  lies  nearest  to  it,  and  when  we  see  it  swing- 
ing round  within  a  short  period  of  three  years  from 
extreme  conservatism  to  extreme  revolutionism,  flouting, 
as  it  were,  all  authority  and  all  traditions,  we  are  entitled 
to  suppose  some  very  powerful  agency  at  work. 

What   is  that  agency?     The  Socialist    Vorw'drts*  in 
commenting  upon  the  result  of  the  by-election  at  Fried- 

*  June  25,    1910. 


berg-Biidingen,  put  the  matter  in  a  nutshell  when  it  said  : 
"A  portion  at  least  of  the  small  farmers  have  now  at  last 
realised  that  they  had  been  duped  by  the  Union  of 
Farmers  and  had  been  sacrificed  in  the  interests  of  the 
large  landlords."  Those  who  have  followed  German  home 
politics  during  the  last  decade  will  not  need  to  be  told 
what  this  means.  It  means  that  the  small  farmers  have 
become  disappointed  with  the  Agrarian  tariff  of  1902, 
which  they  had  been  induced  to  support  as  a  measure 
calculated  to  further  their  interests,  but  which  has  ulti- 
mately turned  out  to  be  to  their  disadvantage  and  to 
further  the  interests  only  of  the  large  landed  proprietor. 
It  is,  then,  according  to  the  Socialist  organ,  the  discovery 
that  high  Protection  has  brought  them  great  harm  that 
has  induced  the  small  farmers  to  revolt  against  the  Junkers 
and  is  driving  them  into  the  most  uncompromising  oppo- 
sition to  the  present  order  of  things. 

There  is  a  good  deal  of  truth  in  this  view,  for  though 
the  last  Agrarian  tariff  has  only  been  in  operation  four 
years,  its  detrimental  effect  on  the  economic  condition  of 
the  small  landholder  and  farmer  is  becoming  patent  to  all 
students  of  German  agriculture.  It  is  desirable  that  in 
this  country,  too,  the  public  should  know  what  this  effect 
is,  seeing  that  our  Tariff  Reformers  lay  great  stress  on 
the  benefits  which  small  farming  would  derive  from  pro- 
tective duties  on  agricultural  produce,  and  even  profess 
to  see  in  them  the  basis  on  which  a  class  of  peasant  pro- 
prietors could  be  created  and  reared  afresh  in  this  country. 

There  was  a  time,  as  everybody  knows,  when  the 
German  Agrarians  were  most  passionate  Free  Traders. 
"It  is  true,"  said  Herr  von  Wedell,  the  leader  of  the 
Conservatives  in  the  Reichstag,  as  late  as  1877,*  "that 
there  are  duties  on  some  agricultural  produce,  such  as 
hops,  butter,  cheese,  and  pigs.  But  these  duties  are 
purely  financial,  and  I  can  tell  you— I  think  all  the  German 

*  Janssen,   "  Liberate   Bauernpolitik,"  Berlin,    1910,  p.  53. 


farmers   will   support  me — that  we  are   prepared  at  any 
moment  to  abolish  them."     Germany  was  at  the  time  a 
great  grain-exporting  country,   and  the  Junkers  had  no 
interest  in  duties  which  would  bring  them  nothing  and 
would  create  difficulties  for  their  exports.     But  in    1879 
Bismarck,  yielding  to  the  pressure  of  the  big  industrialists, 
decided    to    introduce    Protection    for   the    manufacturing 
interests,  and  in  order  to  conciliate  the  Agrarians,   who 
looked    with    disfavour    on    the    industrialisation    of    the 
country,    he    offered    them    a    duty    on    corn.      Not    all 
Agrarians  accepted  the  bargain.     Some  fought  against  it, 
and  only  accepted  a  duty  of  5  marks  per  ton  for  purposes 
of  import  "registration."     But  others  saw  in  the  proposed 
duty  a  compensation  for  the  possible  decrease  of  exports, 
and  even  effected  an  increase  to  10  marks  per  ton.     Herr 
Wedell   now   himself  declared*   that   "the   protection   of 
iron  and  of  rye  is  equally  indispensable  to  the  welfare  of 
the  Fatherland."     "The  welfare  of  the  Fatherland"  has 
since  then  become  synonymous  with  a  high  import  duty 
on  corn  and  other  agricultural  produce.     In  the  very  year 
1879,  when  he  was  creating  industrial  as  well  as  Agrarian 
Protection,   Bismarck  declaredf    that  "even  the  most  in- 
sane Agrarian  will  never  think  of  a  duty  of  30  marks  per 
ton."    But  in  1885  the  duty  was  raised  to  that  figure,  and 
two  years  later  it  even  rose  to  50  marks.    With  the  fall  of 
Bismarck  and  the  advent  of  Caprivi  there  came  a  period 
of  comparative  relaxation,  due  to  the  new  policy  of  com- 
mercial treaties,  and  the  duties  were  lowered  to  35  marks 
for  wheat  and  rye,  28  marks  for  oats,  20  marks  for  barley, 
and  so  all  round.     The  amount  of  Protection  thus  offered 
to  the  pockets  of  the  Junkers  was  still  very  ample,  but  so 
used   had    they   become   to   make   additional   profit   from 

*  Janssen,  I.e.,  p.  53. 

t  Gothein,  "  Der  von  der  staatlichen  Wirtschaftspolitik  in  Deutschland 
erzielte  Effekt  auf  industrielle  und  landwirtschaftliche  Entwicklung," 
Berlin,  1909,  p.  2. 


the  home  consumers  that  its  slight  curtailment  turned 
them  all  into  revolutionists.  "I  propose  to  you,"  ran  the 
famous  appeal  of  one  of  their  stalwarts,  Herr  Rupert,* 
"nothing  more  nor  less  than  that  we  should  all  join  the 
Social  Democrats  and  make  serious  opposition  to  the 
Government.  We  must  show  it  that  we  will  not  stand 
the  bad  treatment  meted  out  to  us,  and  that  we  must 
make  it  feel  our  power.  .  .  .  We  must  shout  so  that  the 
whole  country  shall  hear  us;  we  must  shout  until  our 
voices  reach  the  halls  of  Parliament  and  of  the  Ministries; 
we  must  shout  until  our  voice  is  heard  on  the  very  steps 
of  the  throne."  And  they  did  shout  and  oppose  the 
Government  in  a  manner  that  up  to  that  time  had  been 
unknown  in  Germany.  They  did  not,  indeed,  join  the 
Social  Democrats,  but  they  formed  an  organisation  of 
their  own — the  Union  of  Farmers — which  soon  shook 
heaven  and  earth  with  its  cries.  It  did  not  matter  to 
them  that  the  Prussian  State  Council,  after  considering 
their  demands,  declined  to  accede  to  them,  finding  it  "a 
doubtful  policy  for  the  State  to  increase  the  prime  neces- 
sity of  life."  f  Nor  were  they  much  moved  when  the 
Prussian  Minister  of  Agriculture,  Herr  von  Hammerstein, 
openly  declared  their  agitation  to  be  "dangerous  from  a 
public  point  of  view."  They  did  not  even  mind  being 
branded  by  the  Kaiser  himself  as  "  bread-usurers. "J  They 
proceeded  in  their  agitation  with  an  ever  increasing  energy 
and  unscrupulousness,  gained  the  adherence  of  the  fore- 
most Junkers,  titled  and  otherwise,  in  the  land,  overthrew 
first  Count  Caprivi  and  then  Prince  Hohenlohe,  and  lastly, 
having  obtained  a  Chancellor  after  their  own  heart  in 
Biilow  and  sympathetic  allies  in  the  Clerical  Centre,  they 
succeeded  in  overpowering  all  opposition  and  ultimately, 
after   a    great    parliamentary    fight,    carried    their    object 

*  Janssen,   I.e.,  p.   61. 

t  E.  Wurin,  "  Die  Finanzgeschichte  des  Deutschen  Retches,"  Hamburg, 
1910,  p.   133. 

X    Wurm,  ib. 


through.  On  the  night  of  December  14,  1902,  the  new 
Agrarian  Tariff  was  adopted  in  the  Reichstag  by  a 
majority  of  202  against  100  votes,  and  came  into  force  in 
March,  1906.  By  it  the  duty  on  wheat  was  raised  to 
55  marks  per  ton,  on  rye  to  50  marks,  on  oats  likewise  to 
50  marks,  on  malt  barley  to  40  marks,  on  fresh  meat  to 
270  marks,  on  boneless  fresh  meat  to  224  marks,  on  frozen 
meat  to  350  marks,  and  so  forth  in  a  generous  manner, 
excluding  from  Protection  only  donkeys,  foreign  decora- 
tions, and  dead  bodies  in  coffins. 

Undoubtedly  the  peasants  and  small  farmers  formed 
the  main  support  of  the  Agrarian  agitation.  Even  at 
present,*  out  of  316,000  members  of  the  Union  of  Farmers, 
only  about  2,000  belong  to  the  class  of  large  proprietors, 
who,  it  is  true,  manage  the  Union,  but  represent,  never- 
theless, a  small  minority.  The  bulk  belongs  to  the  peasant 
class,  which  has  been  gained  over  by  specious  arguments 
concerning  high  profits,  exclusion  of  imports,  extension 
of  farm  land,  safety  of  the  home  market,  and  all  the  good 
things  which  are  usually  trotted  out  on  such  occasions. 
Let  us,  then,  consider  how  these  prospects  have  been 
realised. 

The  most  obvious  effect  of  the  Agrarian  duties  has 
been  a  rise  of  prices  of  agricultural  produce.  To  take 
but  the  chief  kinds  of  corn,  wheat  and  rye,  we  find  the 
following  movement  of  prices  (in  marks  per  ton)  on  the 
Berlin  market  :t 

1895  .« 

1900  ... 

1901  ... 

1902  ... 

1903  ... 

1904  ... 

This  table  exhibits  not  only  a  steady  increase  of  prices 


Vheat. 

Rye. 

Wheat. 

Rye. 

142.5 

1 19.8 

1905    ... 

..       174.8 

i5i-3 

151.8 

142.6 

1906    ... 

..       179.6 

160.6 

163.6 

140.7 

1907    ... 

206.3 

193.2 

163. 1 

144.2 

1908    ... 

211. 2 

186.5 

161. 1 

132.2 

1909    ... 

••       233.9 

176-5 

174-4 

i35-i 

1910  (Jan. 

1)       227.1 

167.0 

*  Wurm,  I.e.,  p.  130. 

t    Compiled     from     the    data     of     Berlin     Statistical     Bureau     by     the 
Vorwarts,"  No.   123,   1910  ("  Wirtschaftlicher  Wochenbericht  "). 


s 

of  corn  in  the  course  of  the  last  fifteen  years,  but,  what 
is  of  special  interest  to  us,  a  considerable  jump  in  the 
year  1906-7,  immediately  after  the  new  Tariff  came  into 
force,  and  the  unmistakable  growth  since  then.  It  may, 
of  course,  be  argued  that  this  increase  of  prices  has  been 
noticeable  in  all  countries  and  is  not  confined  to  Germany 
alone.  As  against  this  it  is  but  necessary  to  compare 
the  prices  in  Germany  and  this  country  in  order  to  see 
that  all  through  German  prices  have  been  increased  by 
the  amount  of  the  duty.  Thus  the  annual  average  prices 
of  wheat  per  imperial  quarter  in  England  and  Wales  and 
Prussia  have  been,  since  1875,  as  follows:* 


England  and 

Amount  of 

Wales. 

Prussia. 

Duty. 

s. 

d. 

s. 

d. 

s.     d. 

187s  ... 

45 

2 

4i 

11 

— 

1880   ... 

44 

4       ■•■ 

46 

10 

2      2 

1885  ...     . 

33 

10 

34 

8 

3      2 

1890    ... 

3i 

11 

4i 

2 

6     6% 

1895  ... 

23 

1 

30 

0 

7     VA 

1900    ... 

26 

11 

33 

1 

7     7% 

1905  ... 

29 

8       ... 

36 

7 

7     7X 

1906    ... 

28 

3 

37 

3 

11    10 

1907   ... 

3° 

7       ■•• 

43 

1 

11    10 

1908    ... 

32 

0 

43 

8 

11    10 

Ever  since  the  first  duties  were  introduced  the  prices 
in  Prussia  have  invariably  stood  above  those  in  England 
and  Wales  almost  to  the  exact  amount  of  the  duty.t 
Indeed,  it  could  not  be  otherwise,  for  though  the  pro- 
duction of  corn  cannot  be  regulated  in  a  manner  similar 
to  that  of  manufactured  articles,  in  consequence  of  which 
a  good  crop  must  necessarily  lead  to  a  fall  of  home  prices, 
be  the  import  duty  ever  so  high,  that  danger  has  been 

"  British    and    Foreign    Trade   and    Industry,"    1909    (Cd.    4954),    pp. 
194-195. 

t  According  to  the  "  Vierteljahrshcft  zur  Statistik  des  Deutschen 
Reiches,"  1910,  I.,  the  price  for  wheat  in  the  first  quarter  of  the  current 
year  was  as  follows:  Berlin,  226.2;  London,  164.5;  Odessa,  167.6; 
Chicago,    173.5,    ar|d   Liverpool,    191.3  marks  (shillings)  per   ton. 


obviated  in  Germany  by  a  provision  allowing  a  remission 
of  duty  to  the  exporters  of  corn  in  the  shape  of  certifi- 
cates entitling  the  holders  to  a  rebate  of  equal  amount  on 
certain  articles — coffee,  petroleum,  flour,  and  corn — im- 
ported from  abroad.  Thus,  supposing  one  exports  1,000 
tons  of  wheat,  the  exporter  gets  a  certificate  of  the  value 
of  5,500  marks,  which  is  the  amount  of  duty  which  that 
quantity  of  wheat  would  pay  if  it  were  imported.  The 
certificates  can  then  be  sold  to  an  importer  of  coffee  at 
the  usual  discount,  and  the  rebate  is  turned  into  an  export 
bounty.  In  this  way  the  corn  market  is  effectually  relieved 
from  a  superfluity  of  corn  which  might  have  reduced  the 
price,  and  the  corn  grower,  even  when  selling  abroad  at 
the  world's  market  price,  pockets  his  duty.* 

So  far  so  good — not,  indeed,  for  the  consumer,  but  for 
the  corn  grower.  But  who  is  that  fortunate  person  who 
is  always  secure  of  his  additional  "earning"  of  5  marks 
or  5  marks  50  pfennig  per  ton?  Is  it  the  small  farmer? 
Not  in  the  least.  Prince  Hohenlohe,  in  the  course  of  the 
Agrarian  debate  in  the  Reichstag  on  March  29,  1895, 
spoke  as  follows  :  f 

"Such  proposals  will  by  no  means  benefit  all  the 
farmers.  The  major  portion  of  farming  concerns  will 
derive  no  benefit  from  them,  and  there  are  many  which, 

*  Report  on  Frankfort  for  1908,  pp.  17-19 ;  Wurm,  I.e.,  pp.  141-142. 
This  clever  contrivance  is  operated  under  the  cloak  of  the  law,  which 
permits  the  free  importation  of  goods  intended  for  re-export,  provided 
they  carry  with  them  a  proof  of  their  identity.  In  the  case  of  corn, 
however,  this  latter  provision  was  abolished  in  1894,  as  a  result  of  which 
corn  is  exported  as  if  it  has  been  previously  imported.  The  State  loses 
by  this  veiled  system  of  export  bounties  enormously,  the  exports  being, 
of  course,  much  larger  than  the  imports.  Thus,  between  August  1,  1908, 
and  July  1,  1909,  the  duty  on  rye  yielded  to  the  Exchequer  ,£540,000, 
and  the  expenditure  in  connection  with  the  issue  of  the  remission  certificates 
amounted  to  .£1,940,000.  The  difference — the  taxpayers'  money — was 
pocketed  by  the  exporting  landlords.  Recently  the  Government  made  an 
attempt  to  justify  the  system  in  a  Memorandum  submitted  to  the  Reichstag. 
The  arguments  were  torn  to  shreds  by  the  Association  of  German  Millers 
in  a  counter  Memorandum.     See  "  Kolnische  Zeitung,"  May  31,  1910. 

t    Wurm,  I.e.,  p.   133. 


IO 


so  far  from  being  benefited,  will  only  suffer  from  them. 
.  .  .  Farms  up  to  12  hectares*  have  no  corn  to  sell  at  all, 
but  have  in  most  cases  to  buy  corn  themselves.  In  the 
best  of  cases  farms  above  six  hectares  will,  if  the  soil  is 
favourable,  be  in  a  position  to  meet  the  demand  of  the 
owner  and  his  family  for  corn.  The  number  of  farms 
below  12  hectares  amounts  to  some  four  millions,  that  is, 
76  per  cent,  of  all  farms.  Taking  three  and  half  persons 
per  farm,  we  find  that  a  population  of  something  like 
15  millions  will  derive  no  benefit  from  an  increase  of 
corn  duties — nay,  they  will,  with  few  exceptions,  directly 
suffer  through  an  increased  cost  of  their  living." 

This  was  the  opinion  of  an  Imperial  Chancellor,  him- 
self one  of  the  largest  landowners  in  Germany,  and  there 
can  be  no  doubt  that  it  was  rather  optimistic  than  other- 
wise. It  is  generally  believed  t  that  only  farmers  hold- 
ing more  than  100  hectares  can  and  do  grow  corn  for  sale, 
which  for  milling  or  export  purposes  must  be  of  uniform 
quality  and  offered  in  large  quantities ;  farmers  holding 
between  20  and  100  hectares  do  not  grow  it  regularly, 
and  those  holding  less  than  20  hectares  may  be  said  not 
to  grow  it  at  all  or  grow  it  only  for  their  own  consump- 
tion. The  distribution  of  landed  property  in  Germany 
was,  however,  according  to  the  last  census  of  1907,  as 
follows  (in  hectares)  : 


No. 

Per  cent 

Below    2 

3.378,509 

-         58.7 

From     2  to       5 

1,006,277 

...             !S.5 

From     5  to     20  ... 

1,065,539 

...             18.5 

From  20  to  100  ... 

262,191 

4.4 

Above     100 

23,566 

O.9 

The  first  two  classes  of  farmers  who  certainly  do  not 
grow  any  corn  at  all,  but  have  to  buy  it  for  their  con- 
sumption, form  over  77  per  cent,  of  the  total  number  of 
landed  proprietors.     They  are  directly  damaged  by   the 


*  The  hectare  is  equal  to  2.47  acres, 
t   Janssen,  I.e.,  pp.  67-68. 


II 

corn  duties  and  the  consequent  high  prices.  The  next 
class,  those  farming  between  five  and  20  hectares,  may 
not  suffer  from  the  duties,  but  they  do  not  derive  any 
benefit  from  them,  and  they  form  18.5  per  cent,  of  the 
whole.  It  thus  appears  that  the  high  duties  on  corn  have 
only  benefited  something  like  5  per  cent,  of  the  "total 
number  of  farmers  in  Germany,  those  being  the  largest 
proprietors — the  so-called  big  peasants  (Grossbauern)  and 
the  feudal  landlords,  the  Junkers.  "Welfare  of  the  Father- 
land "  indeed. 

But  if  the  small  farmers  do  not  grow  corn,  perhaps 
they  grow  something  else  on  which  they  benefit  by  Pro- 
tection ?  No  doubt  they  do.  They  breed  live  stock  for 
slaughter  and  dairy  purposes,  which  pursuit  still  forms 
the  main  agricultural  occupation  in  Germany.  Accord- 
ing to  official  statistics,  which  some  regard  as  rather  an 
under-estimate,*  40.6  per  cent,  of  the  net  revenue  yielded 
by  agriculture  comes  from  cattle  rearing  and  the  dairy 
industry,  as  against  26.4  per  cent,  which  is  derived  from 
the  sale  of  corn.  It  is  at  the  same  time  a  pursuit  in  which 
the  small  farmer  engages  to  a  much  greater  extent  than 
the  large  landowner.  To  take  the  figures  of  the  last 
census  in  Prussia,  we  find  t  that  whereas  on  the  large 
farms  of  100  hectares  and  over  the  number  of  cattle  raised 
was  one  per  4.2  hectares  and  that  of  pigs  was  one  per 
7.54  hectares,  on  the  middle-sized  farms  the  corresponding 
figures  were  one  per  1.9  and  1.89  hectares  respectively. 
Only  in  sheep  raising,  which,  of  course,  requires  exten- 
sive pastures  and  is  only  possible  on  large  estates,  the 
farms  of  100  hectares  and  over  show  a  preponderance  over 
the  smaller  sized,  the  ratio  of  sheep  being  one  per  2.4 
hectares  on  the  former,  as  against  one  per  9.6  hectares 
on  the  latter. 

*  Gothein,  I.e.,  p.  9;  cf.  Janssen,  I.e.,  p.  42. 

t "  Korrespondenz   des   Deutschen    Bauernbundes "    in    "Frankfurter 
Zeitung,"  July  8,   1910. 


12 


At  the  same  time  the  prices  of  live  stock  and  meat 
have  risen  considerably.  The  following  shows  the  move- 
ment of  prices  of  the  chief  animals  in  Berlin  in  marks  per 
ioo  kilo,  slaughtering  weight  :* 


Cattle. 

rigs. 

Calves. 

Sheep. 

1886-90 

104.04 

98.07 

98.06 

101.04 

1891-95     .. 

116.07 

102.06 

107.04 

101.00 

1896-1900  .. 

...       114.07 

98.66 

119.04 

107.02 

1900-05 

...       127.03 

m.03 

13509 

126.06 

1906 

...       147.07 

133.08 

162.07 

15707 

1907        .. 

146.06 

no.03 

163.04 

M903 

1908 

139.00 

116.03 

156.06 

140.07 

1909 

131.06 

13303 

156-07 

141.05 

For  reasons  which  will  be  mentioned  below  the  move- 
ment of  prices  of  meat  has  not  been,  and,  indeed,  could 
not  be,  so  uniform  as  that  of  the  prices  of  corn,  but  the 
general  rise  since  the  middle  of  the  'eighties  is  unmistak- 
able, and  the  jump  in  1906  is  especially  very  notable.  It 
would  thus  appear  at  first  glance  that  the  small  farmer, 
who,  as  we  said,  is  for  the  most  part  a  cattle  and  pig 
rearer,  must  have  done,  under  Protection,  very  well.  But 
that  is  only  "at  first  glance,"  as  he  himself  soon  found 
out.  After  the  first  flush  of  enthusiasm  in  1906,  which 
made  him  vote  at  the  elections  of  January,  1907,  for  the 
Junkers  and  other  Protectionists,  the  small  farmer  began 
to  perceive  that  the  high  prices  of  cattle  and  pigs  did  not 
go  by  themselves,  but  were  accompanied,  shadow-like,  by 
high  prices  of  other  articles,  which  went  far  to  neutralise 
the  advantages  from  the  high  meat  prices.  There  were, 
first  of  all,  the  high  prices  for  fodder.  By  the  new  Tariff 
of  1906  the  duty  on  maize  was  suddenly  raised  from  16  to 
30  marks,  that  on  fodder  rye  from  35  to  50  marks,  that 
on  beans  from  15  to  20  marks  per  ton,  and  so  on,  with 
the  sole  exception  of  barley,  the  duty  on  which,  for  fodder 
purposes,  was  reduced  from  20  to  13  marks  per  ton.  These 
duties  render  imported  fodder  absolutely   inaccessible  to 

*    Reports  on   Frankfort  for   1907,  p.    18 ;  for   1908,   p.    20. 


*3 

the  small  farmer,  who  has  thus  to  rely  exclusively  on  his 
own  production  of  these  articles.  Should  the  corn,  hay, 
and  potato  crops  turn  out  satisfactorily,  the  small  farmer 
can,  other  things  being  equal,  make  a  good  profit  out  of 
the  sale  of  his  cattle  or  pigs ;  but  when  the  crops  fail,  as 
not  infrequently  happens,  especially  on  small  farms  with 
insufficiency  of  manure,  the  animals  can  no  longer  be 
fed,  and  they  are  taken  to  market  in  poor  condition  and 
there  sold  at  almost  any  price.  In  such  times  there  is 
an  overwhelming  supply  of  young  animals  on  the  chief 
markets,  and  the  prices  sink  to  a  ruinous  level.  Should, 
immediately  afterwards,  the  prices  rise  again,  the  peasant 
finds  himself  in  a  position  of  not  having  any  more  animals 
to  sell,  in  consequence  of  which  he  is  unable  to  make  use 
of  the  improved  condition  of  the  market.*  Thus — to  take 
an  example  from  recent  years  t — in  1901  the  prices  for 
pigs  stood  at  a  pretty  high  level  of  46  to  47  marks  per 
100  kilos.  In  1904,  however,  the  potato  crop  turned  out 
very  badly,  being  about  14  per  cent,  lower  than  in  the 
previous  year.  At  once  the  small  farmer,  who  could  buy 
no  other  fodder  on  account  of  the  duty,  was  driven  to 
dispose  of  his  pigs,  and  the  prices  sank  to  33-34  marks. 
In  the  course  of  1905  the  prices  rose  again  to  44-49  marks, 
but,  the  sties  being  now  empty,  it  was  only  the  big  farmer 
and  the  Junker,  who  had  been  able  to  withhold  their  pigs 
from  the  market  in  the  previous  year,  who  got  the  benefit 
of  the  high  prices.  Gradually,  however,  the  peasant,  too, 
succeeded  in  rearing  up  a  new  supply  of  pigs,  but  by 
the  time  he  was  beginning  to  make  a  good  profit  there 
came  the  partial  failure  of  the  crops  in  1907,  together 
with  the  crisis,  which  reduced  the  consumption  of  meat, 
and  he  once  more  found  himself  with  a  vast  number  of 
animals  on  his  hands  which  he  had  to  sell  or  else  lose 
altogether.     The  prices   for  pigs   sank   once   more  from 

*  Gothein,  I.e.,  pp.   10-12. 
t  Janssen,  I.e.,  pp.  98-104. 


'4 

54  to  60  marks  per  100  kilos  in  September,  1906,  to 
29.30 — 32  marks  in  the  autumn  of  1907,  and  the  poor 
peasant  had  to  lament  the  duties  on  fodder,  which  render 
a  steady  course  of  production  and  sale  impossible.  This, 
by  the  way,  is  the  reason  why  the  prices  for  cattle  and 
pigs  do  not  move  in  a  regular  manner,  but  are  subject 
to  violent  fluctuations. 

Along  with  the  duties  on  fodder  the  small  farmer  has 
only  too  often  to  lament  the  high  duties  on  living  animals 
which  he  requires  for  rearing  or  breeding  purposes.  It 
is  largely  the  practice  of  the  peasantry  on  the  Eastern 
frontier — in  Posen,  East  and  West  Prussia,  and  in  Upper 
Silesia — to  acquire  young  and  lean  animals  and  rear  them 
or  fatten  them,  as  the  case  may  be,  and  afterwards  re-sell 
them.  The  high  prices  for  live  animals  have  rendered 
this  hitherto  pretty  safe  business  exceedingly  speculative 
and  placed  great  difficulties  in  the  way,  especially  of  the 
smaller  farmer.  It  equally  applies  to  cattle  and  pigs,  and 
still  more  so  to  horses,  the  breeding  of  which  by  the  small 
farmer  has  now  been  almost  entirely  abandoned,  the  duty 
on  horses  amounting  to  50-75  marks  per  head. 

It  is  not  otherwise  with  the  improvement  of  the  stock 
which  is  of  particular  importance  in  the  dairy  industry.* 
Dairy  farming  is  still  carried  on  by  the  small  farmer  to  a 
large  extent,  owing  to  the  high  prices  for  milk,  butter, 
and  similar  produce.  But  here,  too,  he  has  to  contend 
with  ever-increasing  difficulties.  The  climate  of  Germany 
is  generally  dry,  and  with  the  gradual  shrinkage  (if 
meadow  land,  consequent  upon  the  extension  of  corn 
culture  (of  which  we  shall  yet  have  to  say  a  word  or  two 
below),  the  small  farmer  has  to  fall  back  more  and  more 
upon  the  system  of  feeding  his  cattle  in  sheds.  This  has 
a  detrimental  effect  upon  the  cattle  and  renders  the  intro- 
duction of  new  blood  by  foreign  breeds  indispensable. 
But   how   can    the   small    farmer  afford   foreign    varieties 

*  Gothcin,  I.e.,  p.   10. 


*5 

when  the  duty  on  all  horned  cattle  amounts  to  8  marks 
per  ioo  kilos,  of  live  weight,  equal  to  at  least  40  marks 
per  bullock  or  cow  ?  To  this  is  added  the  embargo  which 
is  laid  on  foreign  cattle  ostensibly  for  the  purpose  of  safe- 
guarding native  breeds  from  contamination,  but  in  reality 
to  exclude  foreign  competition.*  No  ruminant  animals 
may  be  imported  from  the  United  Kingdom,  France, 
Italy,  Netherlands,  Russia,  America,  Australia,  and  many 
other  countries,  except,  under  certain  conditions,  from 
Austria-Hungary  and  Denmark.  As  a  consequence  the 
native  race  is  left  unimproved,  and,  with  the  exception  of 
certain  districts,  yields  insufficient  milk,  and  that  of  none 
too  high  a  quality .f 

It  is,  of  course,  impossible,  in  the  absence  of  statistical 
data,  to  estimate  even  approximately  the  damage  done  to 
the  rearing  of  live  stock  and  the  dairy  industry  by  the 
dearness  of  fodder  and  the  practical  exclusion  of  foreign 
breeds.  Indirectly,  however,  the  results  are  seen  in  the 
exceedingly  slow  process  of  expansion  of  these  particular 
branches  of  agriculture,  in  spite  of  the  growth  of  popula- 
tion and  the  rapid  urbanisation  of  Germany.  We  find, 
for  instance^  that  while  in  the  period  between  1896  and 
1906  the  area  under  the  chief  corn  plants  increased  by 
360,625  hectares,  and  that  under  potatoes  by  249,211 
hectares,  meadow  land  only  extended  by  some  42,000 
hectares.  Likewise  we  find§  that,  according  to  the  census 
of  live  stock  in  the  German  Empire  on  December  2,  1907, 
only  the  number  of  pigs  increased  in  the  period  between 
1892  and  1907  in  a  substantial  manner,  namely,  from 
12. 1  to  22.1  millions,  or  82  per  cent.,  whereas  the  number 

*  Wurm,  I.e.,  p.  143.  Recently  about  forty  head  of  German  cattle, 
carefully  selected  for  the  Argentine  Exhibition,  were  rejected  by  the  sanitary 
authorities   at   Buenos   Ayres  as  suffering   from   tuberculosis. 

t   Gothein,  I.e.,  p.   10. 

X  Gothein,  I.e.,  p.  8. 

§    Journal  of  the  Board  of  Agriculture,  June,   1909,  p.  214. 


i6 

of  horses,  including  military,  only  increased  from  3.8  to 
4.3  millions,  that  is,  13  per  cent.,  the  number  of  cattle 
from  17.5  to  20.6  millions,  that  is,  17  per  cent.,  and  the 
number  of  sheep  even  fell  from  13.5  to  7.7  millions.  Con- 
sidering that  the  raising  of  live  stock  is  mainly  the  occupa- 
tion of  the  small  farmer  and  constitutes  his  chief  source 
of  income,  it  is  obvious  that  his  business,  except  in  the 
pig-rearing  branch,  has  not  prospered  much.  It  must, 
moreover,  be  noticed  that  our  statistical  information  does 
not  carry  us  further  than  the  first  year  after  the  introduc- 
tion of  the  new  tariff.  We  shall  have  to  wait  for  the  next 
census  in  order  to  be  able  to  measure  the  full  effect  of  the 
"protective"  duties  on  this  particular  branch  of  agri- 
culture. 

It  is  thus  evident  that  the  German  small  farmer  is,  after 
all,  not  such  a  happy  creature  as  one  is  generally  apt  to 
infer  from  the  high  prices  which  obtain  in  Germany  for 
agricultural  and  dairy  produce.  That  branch  of  agricul- 
ture which  is  prosperous  is  the  one  from  which  he  is  almost 
entirely  excluded,  and  those  branches  in  which  he  is  pre- 
eminently engaged  are  not  prosperous  at  all.*  To  these 
disadvantages  of  a  producer  must  be  added  the  general 

*  A  striking  corroboration  of  the  arguments  set  out  in  the  text  is 
contained  in  a  pamphlet  recently  published  by  Baron  Ferdinand  von  Pantz 
on  the  effects  of  the  Agrarian  duties  in  Austria,  another  highly  "  protected  " 
country  ("  Die  Hochschutzzollpolitik  Hohenblums  und  der  osterreichische 
Bauernstand,"  Vienna,  1910).  The  author  is  himself  a  high  Agrarian,  and 
the  material  contained  in  his  pamphlet  has  been  collected  by  the  Austrian 
Ministry  of  Agriculture.  We  quote  the  following  conclusions  of  Baron 
von  Pantz  from  a  review  of  his  pamphlet  in  the  "  Frankfurter  Zeitung  " 
of  July  8,   1910  : 

"  It  can  be  safely  assumed  that  farms  below  5.75  hectares  are  nowhere 
able  to  sell  corn  or  similar  agricultural  produce.  In  districts  less  favourable 
to  agriculture,  those  situated  in  the  mountains  or  covered  with  woods,  the 
area  of  farms  which  have  to  purchase  their  corn  is  still  larger.  Even 
farms  of  the  extent  of  50  to  100  hectares  are  obliged  to  purchase  quantities 
of  corn  and  of  fodder.  The  author,  therefore,  comes  to  the  conclusion 
that  between  90  and  95  per  cent,  of  the  Austrian  peasantry  have  no  interest 
in  the  high  corn  prices,  but  are,  on  the  contrary,  often  directly  damaged 
by  them.  The  harm  consists  not  only  in  the  enhancement  of  the  cost  of 
living,  but  also  in  the  rise  of  the  costs  of  cattle  production.     Cattle  rearing 


17 

disadvantages  which  he  shares  with  other  consumers,  but 
which,   in  his  case,   react  on  his  position  as  a  producer. 
He  has  to  pay  enhanced  prices  not  only  for  his  clothing 
and  certain  articles  of  his  food,  but  also  for  his  instruments 
of  production — for  his  ploughs  and  other  agricultural  im- 
plements,  for  his  horses  and  horses'   harnesses,   for  his 
farm  utensils,  for  his  paint  and  for  his  tar,  for  his  bricks 
and  for  his  tiles — in  short,  for  everything  which  he  uses 
in  his  life  and  work.     To  take  but  one  apparently  trivial 
example.*     Leather  has  to  pay  a  duty  according  to  weight. 
The  peasant,  even  if  he  be  the  most  cultured  person  on 
earth,  must  have  for  his  field  and  farm  work  heavy  boots. 
These  weigh   in   Germany   not  less  than   3%   lbs.     This 
carries  with  it  a  duty  of  is.  3d.,  as  against  5d.  which  a 
fashionable  young  lady  has  to  pay  on  her  pair  of  dancing 
shoes.     Such  additional  expenditure  tells  heavily  on  the 
peasant's  budget,  and  cannot  easily  be  made  good  by  the 
high  prices  of  corn  which  he  does  not  sell,  or  by  the  prices 
of  meat,  which  constantly  fluctuate,  or  by  the  good  prices 
for    dairy    produce    which    he    cannot    supply    either    in 
adequate  quantities  or  of  adequate  quality. 

But  the  above  are  only  the  direct  effects  of  Protection 
working  chiefly  through  the  high  prices  for  the  auxiliary 


requires  a  considerable  amount  of  human  labour,  and  the  price  of  the 
latter  is  raised  by  the  increased  cost  of  breadstuffs.  Also  the  fodder 
plants  are  expensive.  In  consequence  of  this  the  prices  for  cattle  and  corn 
frequently  exhibit  a  movement  directly  opposite  to  each  other.  Official 
statistics  show  that  high  corn  prices  bring  about  low  prices  for  cattle, 
especially  when  the  hay  crop  turns  out  unsatisfactorily.  A  high  price  for 
corn  compels  the  peasant  to  get  rid  of  his  cattle  at  all  costs,  whereby 
cattle  prices  are  forced  to  a  low  level.  The  author  shows  how,  since  the 
increase  of  Agrarian  duties,  numerous  peasant  farms  have  been  working 
at  a  loss,  and  how,  even  in  the  Alpine  districts,  the  standard  of  life 
among  the  peasantry  has  been  lowered.  He  asserts  that  the  Alpine 
peasantry  is  becoming,  in  consequence  of  the  high  agrarian  duties, 
pauperised  and  must  soon,  like  a  ripe  fruit,  fall  into  the  lap  of  the 
Social  Democracy."  Tout  comme  chea  nous,  may  well  a  German  reader 
say  on  perusing  these  words. 

*  Janssen,  I.e.,  p.  71. 


i8 

material  of  agricultural  production.  There  are  also  some 
indirect  ways  in  which  Protection  works — more  subtly, 
it  is  true,  but  none  the  less  powerfully.  We  shall  single 
out  only  one,  but  that  one  is  already  playing  havoc  with 
the  entire  agricultural  system  of  Germany.  We  mean 
the  way  in  which  the  protective  duties,  by  increasing  the 
prices  for  agricultural  produce,  enhance  almost  to  a  pro- 
hibitive extent  the  rents,  and  ultimately,  through  the 
rents,  drive  the  land  values  (which,  of  course,  are  nothing 
but  capitalised  rents)  to  a  tremendous  height.  A  few  in- 
stances will  suffice  to  illustrate  this  important  movement. 
In  the  course  of  1909  and  the  present  year  a  number  of 
leases  of  Prussian  State  Domains  fell  in  and  were  renewed, 
and  the  rents,  according  to  a  return  made  to  the  Prussian 
Landtag,  moved  upwards  in  the  following  manner.*  One 
estate  used  to  pay  formerly  24.2  marks  per  hectare;  now 
it  will  pay  30.5  marks.  The  rent  of  another  brought  in 
formerly  19.3  marks,  and  now  it  will  amount  to  28.7 
marks.  A  third  estate  was  held  on  lease  in  1873  to  1891 
at  a  rent  of  108.9  marks  per  hectare;  from  1891  to  1909  the 
tenant  paid  120.2  marks;  and  the  new  lease  was  granted 
at  139  marks.  Yet  a  fourth  used  to  yield  84.4  marks  per 
hectare;  now  it  will  yield  113.3  marks.  The  other  dayf 
the  same  administration  leased  out  two  other  domains; 
one,  which  formerly  yielded  only  12,000  marks,  was  now 
leased  out  for  25,100  marks,  and  the  other,  which  hitherto 
carried  a  rent  of  13,000  marks,  will  now  bring  in  30,256 
marks.  Similarly  with  the  purchase  prices  of  land.  A 
nobleman's  estate  (Rittergut)  was  bought  twelve  years  ago 
for  270,000  marks.  That  was  the  time  of  Capri vi's  era  of 
commercial  treaties.  In  1908,  however,  two  years  after 
the  introduction  of  the  new  tariff,  it  was  sold  for  500,000 
marks,  and  at  the  beginning  of  the  present  year  it  was 
sold  once  more  for  750,000  marks. J     Within  a  dozen  years 

*    "  Berliner   Tageblatt,"   January   15,    1910. 
t    "  Frankfurter  Zeitung,"  July  rj,    iqio. 
+    "  Frankfurter  Zeitung,"  July   19,    1910. 


*9 

the  value  of  the  estate  has  thus  increased  200  per  cent. 
Similarly,  an  estate  in  Mecklenburg,  recently  acquired  by 
Prince  Schaumburg-Lippe,  was  bought  in  1890  by  a 
certain  baron  for  80,000  marks.  He  sold  it  a  few  years 
afterwards  for  200,000  marks,  and  now  the  prince  has 
bought  it  for  1,000,000  marks.*  It  is  simply  a  case  of 
capitalisation  of  the  Agrarian  duties,  and  nothing  more. 
How,  then,  does  the  small  farmer  fare  amidst  this  enormous 
growth  of  land  values  ?  It  is  evident  that  it  is  of  no 
advantage  to  him  so  long  as  he  lives,  because,  should  he 
sell  his  land,  he  would  cease  to  be  an  agriculturist  and 
lose  his  sole  source  of  income.  He  is  not  like  a  large 
landowner,  who  can  sell  his  estate  and,  realising  a  good 
sum,  invest  it  in  some  more  profitable  undertaking.  But 
when  he  dies,  what  becomes  of  his  land  ?  It  cannot  feed 
his  several  sons,  seeing  that  it  only  fed  him  alone  with 
great  difficulty.  It  is  the  practicef  in  German  peasant 
families  that  one  of  the  heirs  should  get  the  land  and  pay 
out  the  others  in  cash.  But  if  the  land  values  are  high, 
the  shares  of  the  co-heirs  will  be  equally  high  and  will 
entail  on  the  new  proprietor  a  correspondingly  heavier 
expenditure — in  the  majority  of  cases  a  debt  just  at  the 
beginning  of  his  new  career.  This,  in  the  best  of  cases, 
when  the  land  is  the  peasant's  own.  Should,  however, 
his  land,  or  a  portion  of  it,  be  rented,  it  stands  to  reason 
that  he  has  nothing  to  gain  from  the  high  land  values, 
but  everything  to  lose.  He  can  neither  increase  the  size 
of  his  farm  nor,  perhaps,  retain  his  old  one,  and  his 
position  will  proportionately  deteriorate.  The  growth  of 
land  values,  consequent  upon  the  high  protective  duties, 
is  thus  no  help  but  a  great  hindrance  to  the  development 
of  small  estates  and  small  farming. 

It  may,  then,  be  asked,  what  is  the  evidence  supplied 
by    statistics    with    regard    to    the    movement    of    landed 

*   "  Frankfurter  Zeitung,"  June  8,  1910. 
f  Gothein,  I.e.,  p.  14. 


20 


property  in  Germany  and  its  distribution  ?  Do  the  small 
farmers  increase  or  decrease  in  number,  and  does  the  land, 
owned  or  farmed  by  them,  grow  or  contract?  The  latest 
available  data  refer  to  the  year  1907,  and  they  compare 
with  those  of  the  previous  census  as  follows  : 

Fer  cent,  of  total 
cultivated 
Size  of  Farms  No.  of  Farms.  area  farmed, 

(in  hectares).  1895.  1907.  1895.       1907. 


Below  2    ... 
From     2  to       5 
From     5  to    20 
From  20  to  100 
Above    100 


3,236,367  3, 378.509  •••  5-6  5-4 

1,016,318  1,006,277  ...  10. 1  10.4 

998,804  1,065,539  ...  29.9  32.7 

281,767  262,191  ...  30.3  29.3 

25,061  23,566  ...  24.1  22.2 


This  table  seems  to  contradict  all  the  inferences  to 
which  we  have  been  led  by  the  foregoing  discussion,  and 
to  support  the  views  of  those  who  maintain  that  Protection 
has  been  of  great  advantage  to  the  small  farmer.  The 
larger  farms,  from  20  hectares  onwards,  have  decreased 
both  in  number  and  in  area;  the  middle-sized  farms  have 
increased  in  both;  and  while  the  farms  of  between  two 
and  five  hectares  have  decreased  in  number  and  increased 
in  area,  those  below  two  hectares  have  increased  in  number 
though  decreased  in  area.  On  the  whole,  the  table  shows 
a  slight  transference  of  the  centre  of  gravity  of  German 
agriculture  from  the  larger  to  the  smaller  farms. 

Yet  we  must  not  be  too  hasty  in  accepting  this 
apparently  obvious  conclusion.  The  "farms"  below  two 
hectares  do  not  count  at  all.*  More  than  one-third  of 
them  are  below  a  quarter  of  an  hectare,  and  they  over- 
whelmingly represent  either  kitchen  gardens  or  potato 
patches,  placed  at  the  disposal  of  factory  workers  by 
industrial  magnates,  or  of  agricultural  labourers  by  the 
local  landlord  at  a  nominal  rent,  with  a  view  to  keeping 
the  men  on  the  spot  as  "adscripti  glebae,"  or  in  exchange 
for  services  to  be  rendered  at  certain  seasons.  Their  im- 
portance,  if  any,  consists  in  the  fact  that  their  increase 

*  Wurrn,   I.e.,  pp.    151,    152. 


21 

has  pro  tanto  diminished  the  area  of  the  larger  farms  and 
thus  contributed  to  the  apparent  retrogression  of  the 
figures  in  the  last  two  lines  of  the  table. 

To  some  extent  the  same  may  be  said  of  a  consider- 
able number  of  farms  in  the  next  class,  since  allotments 
of  two  hectares  are  only  suitable  for  keeping  a  few  pigs 
and  growing  a  quantity  of  potatoes  and  other  vegetables, 
and  are  not  infrequently  given  by  the  landlord  to  the 
labourer  as  a  "retaining  fee"  or  as  part  of  his  wages. 
But  with  reference  to  this  and  the  next  class  we  must  bear 
in  mind  the  working  of  the  famous  Polish  Expropriation 
Acts  since  1886,  which  have  been  instrumental,  at  a  great 
expense  to  the  Prussian  State,  in  breaking  up  a  large 
number  of  big  estates  in  the  provinces  of  Posen  and  West 
Prussia  and  in  artificially  creating  in  their  place  a  still 
greater  number  of  small  farms.*  From  that  date  to  the 
end  of  1909  the  Prussian  Government  acquired  475  noble- 
men's estates  and  294  large  peasant  farms,  forming  a 
total  of  370,562  hectares,  at  a  price  of  about  .£17.5  millions. 
The  estates  formed  at  least  seven-eighths  of  this  total 
area,  and  averaged  over  500  hectares  each.  Upon  this 
land  more  than  17,000  families  have  been  settled,  the 
average  size  of  the  holdings,  created  during  the  recent 
years,  being  about  12  hectares. f  This  vast  number  of 
small  farms  artificially  created  will  go  a  long  way  to 
account  for  the  increase  of  farms  of  the  third  class. 

Lastly,  it  is  to  be  observed  that  the  return  which  we 
are  now  discussing  refers  to  the  year  1907,  when  admit- 
tedly the  small  farmers  were  still  labouring  under  the  big 
Protectionist  delusion  and  were  acquiring  and  leasing  land 
in  the  expectation  of  still  bigger  profits  in  the  future. 
Considering  the  disappointment  which  is  now  spreading 
in  their  ranks,  one  is  entitled  to  assume  that  much  of  this 
speculation  has  turned  out  since  then  a  ghastly  failure,  and 

*  Gothein,  I.e.,  pp.  7-8. 

t  The  Times,  April   12,   1910,  "  Prussia  and  the  Poles." 


22 

will  correspondingly  reveal  itself  in  the  figures  of  the  next 
census. 

Another  insight  into  the  agricultural  situation  in 
Germany  is  afforded  by  the  figures  of  the  general  popula- 
tion census,  which,  however,  also  refer  to  the  year  1907. 
The  following  is  the  number  of  agricultural  population, 
according  to  the  last  three  censuses,  in  the  German 
Empire,  and  its  relation  to  the  total  population  :  * 
1907      17,681,176     ...     28.6 

1895       i8,Soi.433       ••■      35-6 

1882       19,225,455       ...       42.0 

These  figures,  however,  include  persons  engaged  in 
forestry  and  gardening,  and  those  also  to  whom  agricul- 
ture is  not  the  main  pursuit  or  who  are  merely  engaged 
as  domestic  servants.  Excluding  these  branches  of  agri- 
cultural industry  and  all  classes  which  are  not  directly 
engaged  in  agriculture,  we  obtain  a  more  favourable 
picture,  namely  : 

1907   9,581,802  ...  15.5 

1895   7.841.858   ...   15.1 

1882   8,267,549   ...   18.2 

It  would  thus  appear  that  the  proper  agricultural  popu- 
lation of  the  German  Empire  has,  since  the  preceding 
census,  increased  not  only  absolutely,  but  even  relatively 
to  the  whole  population.  But  the  significance  of  this  is 
wholly  discounted  by  two  facts.  The  first  is  that  the 
increase  in  the  number  of  persons  engaged  in  agriculture 
is  entirely  due  to  the  increase  in  the  class  of  wage 
labourers,  while  the  class  of  independent  farmers  has, 
on  the  contrary,  decreased.  In  1882  there  were  2,288,033 
independent  farmers;  in  1895,  2,568,725;  and  in  1907, 
2,500,974.  The  number  of  agricultural  labourers  (in- 
cluding a  small  fraction  of  salaried  employes,  such  as 
managers  and  clerks)  was:  1882,  5,848,463;  1895, 
5'723>967;  !907>  7.382,553.  Thus,  between  1882  and  1895, 
the    period    of    comparative    economic    Liberalism,     the 

*  "  Stntistisches  Jnhrbueh  fur  das  Deutsche  Reich,"  1910. 


23  .'  ;  .    .',• 

number  of  independent  farmers  increased,  and  then,  in 
the  period  of  1895-1907,  which  included  two  years  of  high 
Protection,  it  fell  again.  One  is  justified  in  thinking  that 
when  Protection  will  have  had  time  to  work  another  ten 
years  the  census  will  exhibit  a  decrease  in  the  number  of 
independent  farmers  fully  commensurate  with  the  increase 
which  took  place  in  the  twelve  years  of  comparative  free- 
dom of  exchange. 

But  there  is  yet  another  fact,  full  of  significance,  which 
greatly  detracts  from  the  face  value  of  the  table  quoted 
above.  This  is,  that  the  increase  in  the  number  of  persons 
engaged  directly  in  agriculture  proper  is  due  to  an 
enormous  increase  of  female  labour.  The  figures  of  the 
census  show  that  whereas  in  1882  the  number  of  women 
who  were  working  in  agriculture  for  wages  was  2,251,860, 
it  only  increased  in  the  course  of  the  following  twelve 
years  to  2,388,148;  and  then,  in  the  course  of  the  next 
twelve  years  jumped  up  by  two  millions,  to  4,254,488. 
This  fact  is  most  remarkable.  It  shows  that  there  is  no 
longer  any  room  in  German  agriculture  for  the  small 
man,  working  either  as  an  independent  farmer  or  even 
as  a  labourer.  He  drifts  into  towns,  leaving  the  women 
to  take  his  place.  Protection,  which  has  promised  so 
many  blessings  to  the  small  farmer  and  the  labourer,  has 
tremendously  increased  the  process  of  rural  depopulation 
so  far  as  the  men — younger  sons  of  the  small  farmer,  for 
the  most  part — are  concerned.* 

The  shortness  of  time  which  has  elapsed  since  the 
coming  into  force  of  the  last  Protectionist  Tariff  does  not 
allow  of  any  precise  statement  of  facts,  and  all  it  is 
possible  to  do  is  to  observe  the  circumstantial  evidence 
and  note  the  tendencies.  That  these  latter  are  working 
to  an  enormous  extent  in  favour  of  the  larger  landlords, 
especially  the  semi-feudal  Junkers,  is  not  denied  even  by 
them.    That  they  at  the  same  time  must  be  working  largely 

*  Cf.  Gothein,  I.e.,  pp.  15-16. 


*4 

to  the  detriment  of  the  smaller  farmers  is  evident  from 
the  widespread  dissatisfaction  which  is  now  noticeable  in 
their  ranks,  and  is  fully  corroborated  by  an  analysis  of 
the  conditions  under  which  they  have  been  placed  by  the 
Tariff  as  well  as  by  what  indirect  evidence  it  is  possible 
to    collect.      In    the    nature    of    things    the    peasants    in 
Germany,    as    elsewhere,    belong    to   the    least   articulate 
class  of  society,  and  they  themselves  would  for  ever  re- 
main the  last  source  from  which  we  are  likely  to  hear  a 
clear  account  of  their  hardships  and  trials.      It  is  just 
possible  that,  instead  of  giving  vent  to  their  dissatisfac- 
tion by  voting  for  Social   Democrats,   as  they  do   now, 
they  may  one   day   not  only  go  back   to  their  previous 
position,    but    even    demand    increased    Protection    as    a 
remedy    for    those    very    wounds    which    Protection    has 
already  inflicted  upon  them.     "You  suffer,"  the  Junkers, 
who  are  after  their  own  interests,  may  tell  them  yet,  "you 
suffer  not  from  Protection,   but  from  inadequate  Protec- 
tion, and  if  you  want  to  prosper  you  must  demand  a  further 
increase  of  duties."     There  would,   in  view  of  the  well- 
known  ignorance  of  the  rustics,  be  nothing  very  wonder- 
ful in  their  permitting  themselves  once  more  to  be  gulled 
by  these  empty  promises,  and  become  once   more  Pro- 
tectionists, and  that  with  a  vengeance.     This,   however, 
would  clearly  prove  nothing,  and  things  being  such  as 
they  have  been  described  in  the  foregoing  pages,  we  may 
confidently  expect  in  a  few  years'  time  to  see  the  baneful 
effects  of  Protection  exhibited  in  clear  language  in  figures 
directly  bearing   upon   the   subject.     It   is,   at   any    rate, 
obvious  that  the  Protectionists  have  not  made  out  their 
case  with  regard  to  the  alleged  benefits  which  small  farm- 
ing derives  from  high  duties  on  agricultural  produce,  and 
those  in  our  own  countryside  who  are  inclined  to  listen 
to  the  specious  promises  of  the  Tariff  Reformers  on  the 
subject  of  agricultural  revival  through  peasant  proprietor- 
ship will  do  well  to  think  twice,  and  three  times,  before 
they  give  them  a  favourable  reply. 

Printed  bt  Cassell  &  Comi-ant,  Limited,  La  D«.l»  Sautacb,  London.  E.C 


Cobden    Club    Publications. 


The    Book    of    the    International    Free    Trade    Congress. 
Price  is.     By  post,    is.  4d. 

Tariff  Makers:  Their  Aims  and  Methods.  A  Sequel  to 
Fact  v.  Fiction.     Price  is. 

Fallacies  of  Protection :  Being  Bastiat's  "  Sophismes  Econo- 
miques,"  translated  by  Dr.  Stirling,  with  an  Introductory 
Note  by  the  Rt.  Hon.  H.  H.  Asquith,  M.P.     Price  is.  net. 

Insular  Free  Trade,  Theory  and  Experience.  By  Russell 
Rea,  M.P.    6d. 

The  Case  against  Protection.     By  E.  Cozens  Cooke.    3d. 

The  "Scientific"  Tariff:  An  Examination  and  Exposure. 
Price  3d. 

Cobden's  Work  and  Opinions.  By  Lord  Welby  and  Sir  Louis 
Malet.    Price  id. 

Things  Seen  and  Things  Not  Seen.  Translated  from  the 
French  of  F.  Bastiat.     Price  id. 

Shipping  and  Free  Trade.     By  Russell  Rea,  M.P.    Price  3d. 

The  Lessons  of  History  on  Free  Trade  and  Protection.     By 

Sir  Spencer  Walpole.     Price  2d. 

The  Colonial  Conference:  The  Cobden  Club's  Reply  to  the 
Preferential  Proposals.     Price  <Jd. 

What    Protection    Does    for   the    Farmer   and    Labourer. 

By  I.  S.  Leadam.     Price  2d. 

Fact  v.  Fiction  in  Two  Open  Letters  to  Mr.  F.  E.  Smith, 
M.P.,  from  Henry  Vivian,  M.P.     Price  id. 


UNIVERSITY  OF  CALIFORNIA  LIBRARY 
BERKELEY 


P 
T 


Return  to  desk  from  which  borrowed. 
This  book  is  DUE  on  the  last  date  stamped  below. 


I  3Jun,50«S 

I    ,       !9Apr«6.38:' 

j 

I      REC'D  LD 

I    APR  1  5  863 

m       8  19661  ft 


ICLF  (Ml 


LD  21-100m-ll,'49(B71468l6)476 


The  Empire  Aspect  of  Preference.     By  Senator  Pulsford. 
Price  id. 


—    -,   ■  — ._ 


L/~"~ 


Mr        of 


UNIVERSITY  OF  CALIFORNIA  LIBRARY