Skip to main content

Full text of "Initiating successful corporate venture capital investments"

See other formats


fUBRASaESJ 
1^. 


T^C 


m^^^ 


HD28 
.M414 


-9) 


ALFRED  P.  SLOAN  SCHOOL  OF  MANAGEMENT 


INITIATING  SUCCESSFUL 
CORPORATE  VENTURE  CAPITAL  INVESTMENTS 

IAN  C.  YATES  and  EDWARD  B.  ROBERTS 

MIT  SLOAN  SCHOOL  OF  MANAGEMENT 


June  1991 


WP#  3308-91-BPS 


vooACHUSETTS 
iiNSiiiuTE  OF  TECHNOLOGY 
50  MEMORIAL  DRIVE 
CAMBRIDGE,  MASSACHUSETTS  02139 


INITIATING  SUCCESSFUL 
CORPORATE  VENTURE  CAPITAL  INVESTMENTS 

IAN  C.  YATES  and  EDWARD  B.  ROBERTS 

MIT  SLOAN  SCHOOL  OF  MANAGEMENT 

June  1991  WP  #  3308-91-BPS 


MIT  'IBpil 
MAR  3  01932- 


INITIATING  SUCCESSFUL  CORPORATE  VENTURE  CAPITAL  INVESTMENTS* 

IAN  C.  YATES  and  EDWARD  B.  ROBERTS 

Sloan  School  of  Management 
Massachusetts  Institute  of  Technology 

ABSTRACT 

49  large  U.S.  corporations  that  make  corporate  venture  capital  (CVC)  investments  as  part  of  their  new 
business  development  strategies  were  studied.  Venture  capital  firms  were  found  to  be  the  key  deal 
source  of  the  more  successful  CVCs.  Market  familiarity  was  found  to  be  even  more  important  than 
technological  familiarity  in  initiating  strategically  successful  investments  in  small  enterprises.  Later 
round  investments  performed  better  strategically  than  did  early  round  financings.  CVC  financial 
success  flows  from  its  strategic  success,  which  in  turn  is  influenced  favorably  by  strategic  focus. 

EXECUTIVE  SUMMARY 

The  strategies  of  49  large  U.S.  corporations  using  corporate  venture  capital  (CVC)  for  new 
business  development  were  studied  and  evaluated.  Venture  capital  firms  were  found  to  be  the  key  deal 
source  for  CVCs  making  investments  in  small  ventures  that  the  CVCs  judge  to  be  successful 
strategically.  Successful  CVCs  frequently  first  invest  in  venture  capital  funds  as  a  venture  capital 
limited  partner,  then  take  a  more  proactive  long-run  approach  by  investing  side-by-side  with  private 
venture  capitalists  directly  in  start-ups. 

Corporate  familiarity  with  the  venture's  market  was  found  to  be  more  important  in  determining 
strategic  success  than  familiarity  with  the  venture's  technology.  CVCs  must  therefore  evaluate  the 
venture's  market  as  carefully  as  the  venture's  technology  and  seek  to  add  value  to  ventures  through 


*  Address  all  requests  for  information  to  Edward  B.  Roberts,  David  Samoff  Professor  of  Management 
of  Technology,  Sloan  School  of  Management,  Massachusetts  Institute  of  Technology,  50  Memorial 
Drive,  Cambridge,  MA  02139. 


marketing. 

Strategically  successful  CVCs  make  more  investments  in  later  rounds,  foster  supplementary 
business  relationships  between  their  corporation  and  venture  firms,  and  exercise  less  control  over  their 
portfolio  firms,  as  compared  with  less  successful  CVCs.  The  financial  performance  of  CVC  programs 
was  found  to  correlate  positively  with  strategic  success.  CVC  managers  also  report  that  strategic 
success  results  from  a  focussed  strategy. 


INTRODUCTION 

All  companies  committed  to  growth  must  develop  new  businesses.  A  firm's  options  include 
developing  new  products  for  markets  in  which  it  already  participates,  taking  existing  products  to  new 
markets,  or  delivering  new  products  to  markets  it  has  not  traditionally  served. 

Many  funis  have  discovered  the  value  of  corporate  venture  capital  (CVC)  as  an  integral  or 
supplemental  part  of  their  strategic  new  business  development  program,  making  equity  investments  for 
less  than  100  percent  ownership  of  new  or  young  firms.  Throughout  the  history  of  U.S.  business, 
corporate  venturers  have  participated  in  some  extremely  successful  start-ups,  including  DuPont's 
backing  of  GM,  Sears'  minority  ownership  of  Whirlpool,  GE  and  AT&T's  funding  of  RCA,  Haloid's 
(later  becoming  Xerox)  financing  of  Carlson/Battelle  (Rind,  1981),  and,  more  recendy.  Coming's 
investment  in  Genentech,  and  Compaq's  funding  of  Conner  Peripherals. 

These  extremely  successful  corporate  venture  capital  investments  highlight  the  potential  of  CVC 
as  a  strategic  development  tool;  however,  while  CVC  offers  significant  benefits,  many  corporations 
have  become  frustrated  with  CVC  and  have  discontinued  their  corporate  venturing  programs.  The 
complex  processes  that  CVC  entails  and  the  sophistication  required  to  execute  them  effectively  has 
caused  many  corporations  to  eliminate  CVC  programs.  In  addition,  many  corporations  lack  the 
patience  to  give  CVC  programs  the  long  time  necessary  to  grow  to  a  point  where  they  develop 
significant  new  businesses.  Figure  1  schematically  illustrates  the  various  processes  of  CVC  from 
inception  to  execution.  In  approximate  chronological  order,  the  tasks  of  a  strategic  CVC  program  are 
developing  the  venture  program,  initiating  the  investments,  managing  the  investment  portfolio,  and 
assimilating  investments  into  the  corporation's  businesses.  Each  of  these  tasks  must  be  executed 
successfully  for  the  corporation  to  derive  significant  strategic  benefit  from  its  CVC  program. 

The  successes  of  one  task  influence  the  success  criteria  for  another,  complicating  CVC  program 
execution  further.  For  example,  start-ups  which  do  not  meet  the  original  CVC  goals  and  focus  may 
still  become  desirable  investments  if  they  provide  products  or  services  used  by  a  number  of  different 
ponfolio  firms  and  thus  can  foster  synergies  within  a  CVC's  portfolio. 

This  research  attempts  to  establish  the  critical  strategies  employed  by  successful  corporate 
venturers  by  analyzing  the  performance  of  CVC  programs  in  a  quantitative  framework.  Much  of  the 

3 


previous  literature  on  corporate  venturing  provides  anecdotal  case  studies  of  a  specific  firm's  or 
industry's  experiences.  Only  a  few  prior  studies  exist  that  have  attempted  quantitatively  to  determine 
the  causes  of  success  of  CVC  programs. 

We  first  review  the  literature  relevant  to  corporate  venture  capital,  with  particular  focus  on 
previous  attempts  to  identify  factors  critical  to  the  success  of  CVC  programs.  The  objectives  and 
methodology  of  our  research  are  then  presented.  The  results  are  analyzed  and  discussed  next  and  finally 
the  findings  are  summarized. 

CORPORATE  VENTURE  CAPITAL  STRATEGIES:  THE  LITERATURE 

CVC  is  primarily  a  new  business  development  tool  to  help  corporations  in  moving  away  from 
markets  and  technologies  with  which  they  are  famili;u-.  (Robens  and  Berry,  1985)  Further,  CVC  can 
be  used  to  supplement  other  new  business  development  strategies,  providing  firms  with  a  "window  on 
emerging  technologies".  (Roberts,  1980) 

Because  CVC  is  such  a  difficult  new  business  development  tool  to  use  effectively,  many  articles 
have  been  written  to  explore  the  processes  involved  in  CVC.  These  articles  are  written  by  corporate 
strategic  planners,  consultants,  and  private  venture  capitalists  (VCs),  all  of  whom  have  a  different  focus 
when  examining  the  performance  of  CVC  programs.  Many  articles  have  even  appeared  in  the 
"popular"  press,  including  Slutsker  (1984),  Biu-ns  (1984),  Posner  (1984),  Gibson  (1986),  White 
(1989),  Selz  (1990),  and  Buderi  (1990).  This  review  summarizes  some  of  the  significant  work  relating 
exclusively  to  CVC  and  reports  factors  that  authors  indicate  are  critical  to  the  success  of  CVC 
development  efforts.  Literature  written  by  practitioners  and  consultants  involved  in  CVC  is  presented 
first,  followed  by  the  additional  perspectives  derived  from  academic  research. 
Practical  Experience 

In  one  of  the  earliest  articles  describing  CVC  for  new  business  development,  Peterson  (1967) 
discusses  DuPont's  corporate  venturing  activities.  (See  also  Gee  and  Tyler,  1976.)  At  that  time, 
DuPont  probably  had  had  more  experience  in  this  type  of  new  business  development  than  any  other 
corporation.  Peterson  highlights  the  need  for  good  investment  opportunities.  DuPont's  "deal  flow"  is 
reported  to  have  come  from  four  sources:  central  R&D,  other  R&D  throughout  the  firm,  universities, 

4 


government  and  other  research-based  agencies,  and  strategic  planning  and  analysis  of  future  needs. 
DuPont's  appraisal  and  selection  process  included  answers  to  three  critical  questions:  Is  the  potential 
business  large  enough?  Will  its  ROI  be  high  enough?  Will  the  proprietary  position  of  the  venture  offset 
its  risk?  These  questions  have  market,  financial,  and  technology  dimensions,  but  lack  any  evaluation  of 
venture  management  capabilities,  which  violates  the  saying  that  "it's  the  jockey,  not  the  horse,  that  is 
important  in  winning  the  [venture]  race"  (see  MacMillan  et  al.,  1985).  Other  than  the  financial  return 
achieved  in  the  long-run,  Peterson  claims  that  a  corporation  derives  the  additional  benefits  of  fostering 
an  innovative  culture  in  its  own  organization  and  developing  management  expertise. 

Hardymon  et  al.  (1983)  criticize  some  of  the  oversimplifications  of  Peterson's  article,  arguing 
that,  whatever  their  other  merits,  CVC  programs  :u-e  not  a  successful  means  of  promoting 
diversification,  as  Peterson  implied.  They  say  that  CVC  programs  fail  for  at  least  four  reasons.  First, 
corporations  face  a  restricted  universe  of  investment  opportunities  and  often  find  themselves  "left  out" 
of  the  venuire  capital  deal  syndication  network.  In  partial  support  Bygrave  (1988)  provides  a  detailed 
study  of  the  importance  of  "networking"  in  the  venture  capital  community.  Second,  corporations  using 
CVC  for  new  business  development  encounter  problems  acquiring  companies  from  their  portfolios, 
sometimes  called  investment  stalemate.    Third,  many  corporations  see"opaque"  technology  windows 
and  have  difficulty  transferring  technology  from  their  mall  company  portfoUo  to  their  firms'  core 
businesses.  Finally,  Hardymon  et  al.  assert  that  a  conflict  exists  between  running  a  focussed 
diversification  program  and  building  a  healthy  venture  capital  portfolio,  seeing  this  problem  as 
exacerbated  when  corporations  base  venture  managers'  compensation  on  the  portfolio's  financial 
performance. 

While  DuPont  was  the  largest  CVC  of  the  1960s  and  before,  Exxon  was  probably  the  largest  in 
the  1970s.  A  senior  manager  in  Exxon  Enterprises,  Ben  Sykes  (1986)  relates  his  views  on  the  causes 
of  the  rise  and  fall  of  Exxon's  CVC  program.  According  to  Sykes,  Exxon's  experience  shows  that  if 
internal  venturing  is  to  work,  it  must  be  an  important  mainstream  operation.  Sykes  reports  from  Exxon 
data  that  the  venture  manager's  technical  experience  is  not  related  to  start-up  success,  while  his 
management  experience  highly  correlates  with  success.  The  three  primary  diversification  strategies 
Sykes  advocates  are:  (1)  acquire  a  large  company  in  the  target  field;  (2)  start  few  R&D-oriented 

5 


ventures;  and  (3)  use  CVC  investments  primarily  as  "probes". 

Winters  and  Murfin  (1988)  analyze  Lubrizol's  CVC  program,  drawing  some  general 
conclusions  about  CVC.  They  state  that  the  objective  of  most  corporations  is  the  strategic  benefits 
resulting  from  venture  capital  investing,  such  as  acquisitions,  technology  licenses,  product  marketing 
rights,  international  opportunities,  and  windows  on  technology.  These  objectives  are  frequendy  mixed 
with  a  financial  return  objective.  They  report  that  the  most  imponant  factors  for  success  of  a  corporate 
program  are  the  creation  of  a  high-quality  deal  flow  and  the  use  of  outstanding  people  to  interface 
between  the  corporation  and  the  private  VC  world. 

Winters  and  Murfin  applaud  the  creation  of  a  formal  CVC  subsidiary,  like  Lubrizol  Enterprises, 
as  an  effective  way  to  achieve  corporate  strategic  objectives.  Even  with  a  venturing  subsidiary,  the 
corporation  has  assets  of  value  to  a  venture  such  as  "deep  pockets",  reputation,  and  marketing  and 
distribution  capabilities.  Lubrizol's  subsidiary  structure  is  seen  as  facilitating  dealings  with 
entrepreneurs,  acceptance  by  the  private  VC  community,  and  better  internal  relations  within  Lubrizol 
itself.  The  authors  note  numerous  potential  pitfalls  encountered  by  CVC  business  developers.  First, 
corporations  can  have  inadequate  definition  of  strategic  versus  financial  objectives.  Second, 
corporations  tend  to  be  arrogant,  parricuhirly  those  corporations  which  have  been  successful  at  other 
methods  of  business  development.  Third,  corporations  are  slow  to  respond  to  prospective  deals,  which 
they  see  too  few  of  anyway.  They  observe  that  this  lack  of  quality  deal  flow  is  worsened  when  firms 
seek  to  make  early  stage  investments  in  start-ups. 

Private  venture  capitalists  provide  an  additional  perspective  on  the  behavior  of  CVCs.  These 
VCs  invest  side-by-side  with  CVCs  and  often  have  CVCs  as  limited  partners  in  their  funds.  In 
addition,  some  of  the  VCs  which  have  written  articles  also  draw  from  prior  career  experiences  as  CVC 
managers.  Fast  (1981)  recommends  that  CVCs  closely  emulate  the  strategies  of  VCs,  because  he 
argues  that  the  financial  performance  of  VCs  is  superior  (see  Weiss,  1981).  He  says  CVCs  should 
invest  first  in  VC  funds,  then,  as  they  learn  VC,  take  a  more  proactive  role.  Fast  outlines  a  number  of 
factors  which  he  believes  can  ensure  the  success  of  a  CVC  program.  Like  Winters  and  Murfin  (1988), 
Fast  suggests  that  CVCs  be  organized  as  limited  partnerships  because  this  structure  "forces"  patience  as 
corporations  cannot  divest,  investments  are  staged  in  a  manner  consistent  with  ventures's  development 

6 


life-cycle,  and  an  easy-to-implement  incentive-based  compensation  system  is  provided.  Further,  Fast 
asserts  that  CVCs  should  follow  the  same  intervention  and  management  guidelines  as  VCs,  being 
hands-off  and  big-picnjre  oriented,  avoiding  "micromanagment",  and  planning  for  the  venture's 
financing  needs. 

Kenneth  Rind,  who  worked  as  a  corporate  venture  capitalist  for  Xerox  before  becoming  a 
private  venture  capitalist,  has  written  extensively  on  CVC  (Rind,  1981;  Golden  and  Rind,  1984;  Rind, 
1989).  Rind  concludes  that  CVC  is  a  useful  tool  for  corporate  development,  but  is  difficult  to  do 
internally;  thus,  outside  partnership  investment  can  serve  as  a  useful  alternative  first  step  or  as  a 
supplement.  CVC  is  reportedly  difficult  because  of  a  lack  of  appropriately  skilled  people,  contradictory 
rationales,  legal  problems  between  fiduciary  responsibility  and  corporate  opportunity,  and  inadequate 
corporate  time  horizons.  However,  Rind  (1989)  does  point  out  a  number  of  advantages  that  accrue  to 
small  firms  which  have  a  corporate  investor  such  as:  assistance  in  all  corporate  endeavors,  credibility 
with  customers,  banks,  and  others,  relief  from  many  specialized  aspects  of  business  (i.e.,  international 
marketing),  immediate  income  from  R&D  contracts,  deep  pockets  through  a  more  flexible,  lower  cost 
financing  package,  and,  finally,  a  potential  merger  partner.  Ford  and  Ryan  (1981)  discuss  some  of  the 
benefits  of  having  a  corporate  partner  to  aid  in  marketing  efforts  in  greater  detail. 

Most  recently  Hegg  (1990)  revealed  details  of  3M's  $75  million  global  CVC  program,  with 
participations  in  27  private  venture  capital  limited  partnerships  (VCLPs).  He  reports  both  significant 
financial  returns  and  strong  strategic  linkage  to  3M's  business  units,  including  acquisition  of  some  of 
the  portfolio  companies. 
Academic  Studies 

Because  CVC  has  been  used  as  a  significant  new  business  development  tool  for  several 
decades,  significant  academic  research  has  been  devoted  to  addressing  various  aspects  of  CVC.  One  of 
the  largest  programs  of  this  research  has  been  carried  out  at  the  Snider  Entrepreneurial  Center  of  the 
Wharton  School  by  MacMillan,  Siegel,  and  co-workers  (MacMillan  et  al.,  1985;  MacMillan  et  al., 
1987;  DeSarbo  et  al.,  1987;  Siegel  et  al.,  1988).  These  works  emphasize  the  importance  of  corporate 
venture  managers  in  determining  the  success  of  a  given  CVC  program.  These  key  managers  must  be 
high-quality,  well-compensated,  and  should  be  given  the  flexibility  to  operate  independently,  possibly 

7 


being  established  in  a  group  separate  from  the  corporation.  These  studies  indicate  that  successful  CVCs 
should  focus  on  achieving  fmancial  objectives.  Thus,  CVCs  should  behave  in  many  respects,  such  as 
investment  selection  and  company  management,  like  a  private  venture  capitalist.  Their  conclusion 
regarding  the  similarities  between  the  behavior  of  successful  CVCs  and  successful  private  VCs  match 
the  opinionsof  Fast  (1981). 

Hlavacek  et  al.  (1977)  provide  early  motivation  for  strategic  use  of  CYC,  stating  that  studies 
indicate  that  over  74%  of  technological  innovations  originate  in  small  firms.  Yet  acquisition  too 
frequently  removes  the  advantages  that  a  small  company  might  bring  to  a  large  corporation.  Successful 
CVC  partnering  is  reported  to  result  from  a  threefold  strategy.  First,  corporations  should  locate  a 
company  which  has  strengths  where  it  has  weaknesses.  Second,  the  large  firm  should  have  an 
entrenched  and  extensive  marketing  organization  that  is  capable  of  fully  exploiting  the  venture's 
proposed  technology.  Finally,  and  perhaps  most  importantly,  the  large  firm  must  be  "hungry"  and 
willing  to  do  everything  it  takes  to  ensure  the  venture's  success. 

Greenthal  and  Larson's  (1982)  information  on  CVC  leads  them  to  caution  venturing 
corporations  that  they  must  have  realistic  goals.  Corporations  should  seek  either  to  acquire  new 
businesses,  gain  access  to  new  technology,  or,  most  simply,  generate  a  sizable  return  on  investment. 
Greenthal  and  Larson  believe  that  organizing  CVC  with  these  realistic  goals  in  mind  is  key.  If  the 
corporation  is  focussed  solely  on  ROI,  then  becoming  a  limited  partner  of  a  private  venture  capital  fund 
is  appropriate,  otherwise  the  CVC  group  must  be  more  proactive.  They  assert  that  the  success  of  CVC 
groups  is  affected  primarily  by  their  position  in  the  organization,  the  management  systems  controlling 
the  CVC  managers,  the  quality  of  the  CVC  managers,  and  the  compensation  of  these  managers. 

Levine  (1983)  expands  on  Greenthal  and  Larson's  work,  concluding  that  the  "inside  track"  on 
new  technologies  should  be  more  important  to  corporations  than  ROI.  CVCs  have  problems  because 
they  feel  that  they  have  to  dictate  the  small  firm's  product  and  technology  decisions.  In  addition,  CVCs 
are  treated  differendy  by  private  VCs  because  they  assume  that  CVCs  are  not  under  the  gun  to  hquidate, 
as  private  VCs  are. 

Block,  Sykes  and  their  co-workers  at  New  York  University  have  produced  additional  pertinent 
recent  studies  (Block,  1983;  Block  and  Ornati,  1987;  Sykes  and  Block,  1989;  Sykes,  1990).  Block 

8 


and  Omati  (1987)  find  that  performance  incentives  for  CVC  managers  are  not  essential,  because  they 
often  lack  sufficient  time  horizons.  Sykes  and  Block  (1989)  indicate  that  the  two  major  obstacles  to 
CVC  success  are  (1)  conflicts  between  the  formal  policies  of  the  large  firm  and  the  needs  of  the  small 
firm,  and  (2)  misdirection  of  small  firm  because  of  irrelevant  and  damaging  corporate  management 
practices. 

Sykes'  most  recent  article  on  CVC  (1990)  outlines  many  drivers  of  strategic  success  for  CVC 
programs.  Sykes  surveyed  a  large  number  of  CVCs  and  determined  that  their  success  depends  on 
mutually  beneficial  strategic  objectives  between  the  small  and  the  large  firms,  frequent  and  open 
communications  between  the  corporation  and  the  venture,  and  financial  returns  on  investment.  Direct, 
proactive  investment  is  seen  to  be  better  if  only  one  strategy  is  chosen,  but  being  a  limited  partner  in  a 
private  VC  fund  is  identified  by  Sykes  as  providing  "deal  flow"  for  direct  investment  possibilities.  He 
remarks  that  effective  relationships  between  CVCs  and  VCs  are  built  over  extended  time  periods, 
usually  by  co-investing  and  serving  together  on  the  boards  of  directors  of  start-ups.  Factors  found  not 
to  influence  the  success  of  CVC  programs  itre  CVC  manager  experience  and  compensation,  the 
organizational  position  of  corporate  contact,  the  source  of  direct  investment,  and  the  number  of 
corporate  investors  in  a  VCLP. 

OBJECTIVES  AND  METHODOLOGY 
Objectives 

The  study  described  here  is  directed  at  understanding  how  to  improve  the  process  of  initiating 
investments,  one  stage  of  the  process  of  new  business  development  through  CVC  (Figure  1)  in  which 
little  previous  research  has  been  done.  The  process  of  initiating  investments  has  been  subdivided  into 
three  separate,  but  related,  activities:  (1)  uncovering  good  investment  opportunities;  (2)  selecting  which 
investments  to  make;  and  (3)  structuring  and  managing  the  investments.  Specifically,  this  research 
attempts  to: 

•determine  the  best  methods  for  CVCs  to  uncover  investment  opportunities, 

•find  the  determinants  of  success  in  the  investment  identification  process, 

•establish  guidelines  for  structuring  and  managing  CVC  investments. 

9 


Methodology 

To  study  the  CVC  programs  of  large  U.S.  corporations,  a  questionnaire  on  direct  investment  in 
small  companies  was  sent  to  over  150  growth-oriented  large  firms,  hoping  that  this  approach  would 
ensure  that  a  large  fraction  of  those  corporations  using  CVC  would  be  contacted.  To  increase  the 
significance  of  the  questionnaire's  results,  great  care  was  taken  to  ensure  that  the  surveys  were  sent 
directly  to  someone  involved  on  a  day-to-day  basis  with  new  business  development.  (The  complete 
questionnaire  is  available  from  the  authors.)  54  firms  responded  to  this  survey,  with  49  providing 
complete,  quantitative  responses.  The  other  five  respondents  had  programs  that  were  not  "old"  enough 
for  meaningful  results,  according  to  their  replies.  If,  as  asserted  by  Sykes  (1990),  only  80  U.S.  firms 
have  CVC  programs,  49  firms  indeed  constitute  a  broad  sample  of  the  corporate  venturers.  75%  of  the 
respondents  were  large  multinational  corporations,  with  60%  being  in  the  Fortune  5(X)  and  15%  in  the 
Forbes  International  500.  The  responding  firms  represent  a  wide  range  of  industries  and  are  believed  to 
be  representative  of  the  spectrum  of  CVCs.  Half  of  the  fums  (25  of  49)  were  also  contacted  in 
follow-up  phone  conversations,  selected  based  on  their  pursuit  of  a  particular  strategy  of  interest  to  us, 
as  pointed  out  later  in  this  paper.  The  telephone  conversations  qualitatively  confirmed  the  conclusions 
drawn  from  statistical  analyses  and  explored  some  of  the  more  unique  approaches  to  CVC  in  greater 
detail.  Finally,  22  of  the  49  firms  responded  to  another  follow-up  mail  survey  (sent  to  all  49  initial 
respondents)  that  focussed  on  investment  structure  and  venture  management.  These  22  are  a  reasonably 
representative  subset  of  the  original  group,  as  is  discussed  further  when  these  data  are  analyzed. 

For  the  sake  of  hypothesis  testing  a  firm  is  classified  as  "strategically  successful"  based  on 
self-assessment  by  the  respondent  that  the  firm's  CVC  program  was  producing  a  rate  of  new  business 
development  that  was  superior  to  that  from  internal  development  effons,  given  the  same  level  of 
resources.  The  potential  bias  in  these  evaluations  is  evident  and  no  systematic  objective  information 
was  collected.  Furthermore,  although  a  "success"  score  on  this  question  could  result  from  poor  internal 
development  effons,  it  was  felt  that  this  would  not  typically  be  the  case. 

This  definition  of  success  can  be  justified  for  theoretical  and  practical  reasons.  First,  from  a 
theoretical  standpoint,  this  definition  normalizes  for  firms  which  are  situated  in  high  growth  industries 
and  may  experience  high  rates  of  new  business  development  from  all  their  new  business  development 

10 


activities.  In  addition,  from  a  theoretical  standpoint,  normalizing  for  equivalent  resource  commitment 
removes  biases  introduced  by  top  management  decisions  to  emphasize  one  mode  of  new  business 
development  over  another.  From  a  practical  standpoint,  despite  room  for  bias  in  the  direction  of  overly 
positive  appraisal,  the  definition  in  fact  divided  the  responding  corporations  almost  in  half,  with  a  wide 
range  of  self-scores.  Most  importantly,  it  provided  two  groups  that  exhibit  markedly  different  behaviors 
and  are  clearly  pursuing  dramatically  different  strategies  in  their  CVCs. 

UNCOVERING  GOOD  INVESTMENT  OPPORTUNITIES 

Uncovering  good  investment  opponuniries  that  are  worth  pursuing  is  extremely  difficult;  it's 
like  "searching  for  a  needle  in  a  hay  stack".  A  number  of  studies  (Peterson,  1967;  Hardymon  et  al., 
1983;  Winters  and  Murfin,  1988;  Siegel  et  al.,  1988;  Sykes,  1990)  identify  establishing  and 
maintaining  a  high  quality  "deal  flow"  as  critical  to  the  success  of  CYC  programs.  To  evaluate  the  deal 
sources  of  corporations,  their  primary  sources  of  investment  opportunities  as  well  as  the  distribution  of 
all  sources  of  investment  opportunities  were  examined.  Table  1  shows  the  average  distribution  of  all 
deal  sources  for  all  49  firms  in  the  study.  In-house  people  are  the  largest  source  of  deals  (32%), 
followed  closely  by  venture  capital  firms  (28.2%);  together  these  top  two  deal  sources  represent  over 
60%  of  all  investment  opportunities.  In  his  study  of  CYC  strategies,  Sykes  (1990)  also  finds  these  two 
to  be  the  predominant  deal  sources,  although  venture  capital  firms  are  identified  as  being  more 
important  in  his  study  (27%  for  YCs  versus  20%  for  In-house);  Sykes'  study  focusses  more  on  YC 
limited  partnerships,  which  may  account  for  the  quantitative  differences. 

Figures  2  and  3  show  the  differences  between  successful  and  less  successful  firms,  on  Uie  basis 
of  the  average  of  all  sources  and  the  primary  sources  of  investment  opportunities.  Firms  that  are  more 
successful  use  venture  capital  firms  as  a  deal  source  to  a  much  greater  extent  tiian  do  less  successful 
firms.  Table  2  presents  a  statistical  comparison  of  successful  and  unsuccessful  CYCs,  verifying  that  a 
statistically  significant  difference  exists  between  the  sources  of  investment  opportunities.  The  venture 
capital  community  is  clearly  the  best  source  of  a  high  quantity  of  high  quality  deals,  perhaps  because 
venture  capitalists  add  value  to  their  portfolio  firms,  thereby  reducing  the  probability  of  venture  failure. 
Deal  Sourcing  from  Venture  Capitalists 

1  1 


These  analyses  strongly  indicate  that  a  venture  capital  deal  sourcing  network  plays  an  integral 
role  in  a  successful  CVC  program.  To  determine  how  large  corporations  cultivate  such  a  network, 
CVCs  that  were  classified  as  successful  and  that  also  had  sourced  more  than  33%  of  their  deals  from 
the  venture  capital  (VC)  community  were  contacted.  In  addition,  a  number  of  venture  capitalists  with 
experience  in  or  with  corporate  venture  capital  were  also  interviewed. 

These  successful  CVCs  indicate  that  their  primary  methods  of  cultivating  deal  flow  from  the 
venture  capital  community  are: 

•investing  direcdy  in  VC  portfolio  firms  (usually  called  co-investing), 

•networking  with  VCs  without  investing  (see  Bygrave,  1988), 

•contacting  those  VCs  which  hold  some  of  their  corporation's  pension  assets. 

According  to  VCs  (see  also  Golden  and  Rind,  1984),  the  factors  which  give  CVCs  credibiHty  in 
the  co-investing  process  include:reputations  of  corporate  people  involved  in  venturing,  demonstrated 
ability  to  both  generate  and  share  leads,  resources  to  constructively  evaluate  ventures  on  a  timely  basis, 
and  commitment  to  be  in  venturing  for  the  long-run.  In  addition  to  these  qualities,  successful  CVCs 
added  the  following  pointers  which  they  said  could  help  corporate  venturers  become  pan  of  the  VC 
community:  ability  to  co-exist  with  VCs,  flexibiUty  with  respect  to  deal  structure  and  ultimate 
acquisition,  and  willingness  to  provide  VCs  with  a  "way  out"  or  liquidity  in  later  rounds  (see  also 
Slutsker,  1984,  and  Buderi,  1990). 

Based  on  the  interviews,  investing  in  VC  funds,  i.e.  becoming  a  venture  capital  limited  partner 
(VCLP),  appears  to  be  useful  primarily  as  an  entry  strategy,  to  be  used  in  the  early  stages  of  the  CVC 
program.  Continuing  to  be  a  VCLP  does  not  appear  to  be  critical  for  long-run  strategic  performance, 
as  corporations  have  to  move  into  a  more  proactive  role  in  the  venturing  process,  making  and  managing 
direct  investments  in  small  companies  themselves  (see  also  Fast,  1981). 

Although  some  VCs  recommend  that  a  corporation  become  a  VCLP  to  learn  about  "how  the  VC 
game  is  played"  and  to  develop  credibility  within  the  VC  community  (see  Golden  and  Rind,  1984), 
successful  CVCs  criticized  being  a  VCLP  as  a  long-run  strategy  for  a  number  of  reasons.  First,  for 
corporations  with  a  fixed  pool  of  venturing  funds,  being  a  VCLP  in  the  long-run  is  reportedly  an 
"expensive"  method  of  generating  deal  flow.  Second,  as  a  VCLP,  some  corporations  see  "opaque" 

12 


windows  on  technology,  getting  deals  only  after  the  fund  has  rejected  them.  Alternatively,  "opaque" 
windows  may  result  from  corporate  venturers'  lack  of  proactive  efforts,  expecting  that  they  will  be 
"spoon  fed"  by  the  VCs.  Third,  becoming  a  VCLP  may  signal  that  a  corporation  is  unwilling  or  unable 
to  participate  in  the  high  value-adding  activities  of  venture  capital,  such  as  deal  evaluation  and  portfolio 
firm  management.  Thus,  some  VCs  seem  to  see  corporate  VCLPs  as  "dumb  money".  The  conclusion 
that  being  a  VCLP  is  not  a  long-run  strategy  may  not  apply  to  dedicated,  single-corporation  VC  funds, 
which  can  be  similar  strategically  to  CVC  subsidiaries. 

INVESTMENT  SELECTION  AND  STRATEGY 

Selecting  which  investments  to  make  is  challenging  because,  even  after  an  exhaustive  search, 
many  investment  opportunities  are  not  worth  pursuing.  Thus,  separating  the  "wheat  from  the  chaff  is 
a  vital  part  of  a  successful  venture  process.  Indeed,  private  venture  capitalists,  who  are  not  "restricted" 
by  strategic  objectives  as  corporations  are,  report  that  they  invest  in  only  about  1-2%  of  all  deals  they 
see  (Rind,  1982). 

In  this  section,  we  first  discuss  the  effect  of  strategy  on  the  success  of  CVC  programs,  paying 
particular  attention  to  strategies  of  diversification  with  respect  to  both  market  and  technology.  These 
analyses  lead  naturally  into  a  brief  discussion  of  selection  criteria  for  successful  CVCs. 
The  Effect  of  Diversification 

Many  studies  (see  Rumelt,  1982;  Peters  and  Waterman,  1982;  Roberts  and  Berry,  1985;  Zirger 
and  Maidique,  1990)  report  that  new  business  development  through  diversification  is  harder  than 
"sticking-to-the-knitting".  Our  data  in  Figure  4  also  show  that  new  business  development  in 
diversified  areas  through  CVC  is  more  difficult  than  non-diversification  investments. 

Although  a  significant  difference  exists  between  the  average  success  of  diversifying  CVC  firms 
and  stick-to-the^nitting  firms  as  shown  in  Figure  4,  diversification  seems  more  feasible  than  is 
implied  by  some  authors.  This  finding  that  CVC  is  a  reasonable  method  of  new  business  development 
for  diversifying  firms  is  consistent  with  Roberts  and  Berry's  conclusion  (1985)  that  CVC  is  the  most 
viable  method  of  new  business  development  for  firms  seeking  to  diversify. 

Because  diversification  has  both  technology  and  market  dimensions,  the  effects  of  market  and 

13 


technology  familiarity  on  the  success  of  CVC  programs  were  examined  separately.  Figures  5  and  6 
show  the  average  success  rating  for  those  following  market  and  technology  diversification  and 
stick-to-the-knitting  strategies.  Corporate  familiarity  with  the  venture's  market  is  as  important  in 
determining  strategic  success  as  familiarity  with  the  venture's  technology.  However,  examining  the 
differences  between  strategically  "successful"  and  "unsuccessful"  firms,  market  familiarity  is  shown  to 
be  even  more  important  in  Table  3.  That  closeness  to  market  is  more  important  than  closeness  to 
technology  has  been  noted  previously  by  Sykes  (1986),  MacMillan  et  al.  (1987),  and  Roberts  and 
Meyer  (1991).  Table  3  shows  that  the  market  familiarity  of  successful  firms  differs  significantly,  at  the 
92%  confidence  level,  fi-om  that  of  unsuccessful  firms.  For  technology  familiarity,  the  level  of 
confidence  that  a  difference  exists  between  successful  and  unsuccessful  firms  is  less  than  50%. 
Selection  Criteria  of  Successful  CVCs 

There  have  been  at  least  four  significant  studies  on  the  investment  selection  criteria  of  CVCs 
(MacMillan  et  al.,  1987;  DeSarbo  et  al.,  1987;  Siegel  et  al.,  1988;  MacMillan  et  al.,  1985).  Table  4 
shows  the  difference  in  selection  criteria  of  CVCs  and  VCs  from  one  study.  Some  natural  differences 
exist,  such  as  the  three  "strategic"  criteria  that  are  used  only  by  CVCs;  however,  neglecung  the  two 
criteria,  "articulate  in  discussing  venture"  and  "track  record  relevant  to  venture",  might  be  serious 
oversights  by  CVCs.  According  to  Siegel  et  al.  (1988),  these  two  criteria  are  statistically  significant 
determinants  of  success.  Table  4  also  presents  information  useful  for  designing  selection  criteria  for 
corporations  considering  launching  a  CVC  program. 

From  conversations  with  a  number  of  CVCs,  it  appears  that  many  CVCs  seem  to  have  a  "blind 
spot"  when  it  comes  to  some  aspects  of  investment  evaluation  (see  also  Peterson,  1967).  CVCs  need  to 
make  sure  their  selection  criteria  are  "balanced"  with  respect  to  evaluating  the  venture's  market  and 
management  team  and  not  too  focussed  on  evaluating  just  the  venture's  technology.  CVCs  with 
technical  backgrounds  or  who  are  affiliated  with  the  corporation's  R&D  may  have  a  greater  tendency  to 
overemphasize  technology  in  their  selection  criteria.  The  analyses  shown  in  Figures  5  and  6  and  Table 
3  demonstrate  that  market  familiarity  can  be  even  more  important  than  technology  familiarity  in 
generating  strategically  successful  outcomes.  Thus,  CVC  investment  selection  criteria  and  due 
diligence  should  be  at  least  as  heavily,  if  not  more  heavily,  weighted  towards  the  venture's  proposed 

14 


market  as  they  are  to  its  technology. 

INVESTMENT  TIMING  AND  STRUCTURE 

Having  found  and  selected  a  market-technology  focus,  the  timing,  structure  and  management  of 
the  initial  investment  in  a  venture  may  define  the  investment's  ultimate  strategic  potential  for  the 
corporation.  Incorrectly  timed  and  poorly  structured  corporate  alliances  can  be  as  fatal  to  a  start-up  as 
misunderstood  markets  or  infeasible  technologies.  This  section  first  discusses  the  stage  in  the  growth 
of  a  venture  during  which  the  more  successful  CVCs  invest  and  then  treats  some  of  the  issues  relating 
to  investment  structure  and  management  of  ventures  by  the  corporation. 
The  Effect  of  Venture  Age 

Investing  early  in  a  venture's  life  is  riskier,  but  a  corporation  can  place  more  "bets"  for  its 
investment  dollar  and  learn  sooner  about  emerging  technologies  and  markets.  Figures  7  and  8  contrast 
the  investment  timing  of  more  successful  and  less  successful  furos.  Figure  7  shows  that  strategically 
successful  CVCs  make  more  investments  in  later  rounds,  as  compared  with  less  successful  firms. 
Figure  8  highlights  that  this  later  round  investment  strategy  is  even  favored  by  successful  diversifying 
firms,  indicating  that  this  effect  is  not  a  stick-to-the-knitting-versus-diversification  effect.  Table  5 
shows  that  the  differences  in  investment  timing  between  more  successful  and  less  successful  CVCs  are 
statistically  significant,  with  the  strategy  of  later  round  investments  being  much  more  successful. 

At  least  six  possible  explanations  are  plausible  for  this  effect  of  investment  timing.  First,  the 
effect  might  simply  represent  the  expected  risk-return  tradeoff  that  changes  through  the  growth  of  a 
start-up.  Second,  in  later  investments,  the  match  between  the  venture's  strategy  and  the  corporation's 
strategy  can  be  more  easily  ensured  due  to  more  information  being  available.  Third,  in  early 
investments,  the  corporation  may  structure  the  investment  so  that  the  incentive  for  innovation  within  the 
venture  is  removed.  Fourth,  in  forcing  stan-up  companies  to  have  synergies  with  the  corporate 
portfolio,  corporations  may  "misguide"  the  venture,  as  is  discussed  by  Levine  (1983).  Fifth, 
corporations  that  invest  early  may  be  too  "conservative"  and  therefore  not  invest  enough  to  make  this 
strategy  work  effectively.  Finally,  the  effect  may  be  tautological,  reflecting  additional  later  round 
investments  by  CVCs  into  those  earlier  investments  that  turn  out  to  be  strategic  "fits"  with  the 

15 


corporation!  Whatever  the  possible  explanation,  the  results  cannot  be  ignored  by  CVCs. 
The  Corporation-Venture  Interface 

The  lower  strategic  yield  from  early  round  investments  might  potentially  be  mitigated  by 
well-structured  and  correctly-managed  investments.  A  second  survey,  focussed  on  investment 
structure,  was  sent  to  the  respondents  of  the  first  survey.  While  only  22  of  the  49  firms  responded, 
analysis  of  these  results  provides  at  least  qualitative  information  regarding  the  critical  behaviors  of 
CVCs.   14  of  these  22  respondents  were  successful  by  our  definition,  so  this  is  a  reasonably 
representative  group. 

Figure  9  shows  that  on  average  strategically  successful  and  unsuccessful  CVCs  use  a  similar 
spectrum  of  investment  structures,  with  both  groups  using  equity  or  convertible  debt  over  60%  of  the 
time.  This  similarity  in  investments  may  be  due  to  the  fact  that  CVCs  must  negotiate  these  investments 
with  the  start-up  and  other  investors,  all  of  whom  probably  prefer  corporations  to  use  "straight"  equity. 
The  more  successful  CVC  firms  do  form  pannerships  in  which  they  are  the  limited  partner  (LP) 
approximately  twice  as  often  as  do  unsuccessful  firms.  These  types  of  investments  are  not  used 
firequently,  but  can  be  a  useful  way  for  corporations  to  exploit  a  start-up's  technology  in  a  market 
which  is  defined  by  user-type  or  geography.  Again,  this  is  at  least  in  part  tautological,  i.e.,  closeness 
of  fit  strategically  produces  greater  likelihood  of  adopting  the  closer  ties  of  a  partnership,  and  vice 
versa. 

Figure  10  shows  the  average  initial  equity  ownership  percent,  extent  of  supplementary 
relationships,  and  magnitude  of  control  of  CVCs.  The  magnitude  of  CVC  control  is  measured  by  four 
different  parameters:  %  of  investments  in  which  CVCs  manage  the  operations  on  a  day-to-day  basis, 
%  of  investments  in  which  CVCs  have  a  board  member,  %  of  investments  in  which  CVCs  control  the 
board,  and  %  of  investments  in  which  CVCs  can  replace  the  start-up's  CEO.  Successful  CVCs  have  a 
lower  average  initial  equity  position  than  unsuccessful  CVCs,  which  may  indicate  that  successful  CVCs 
place  more  "bets"  by  not  "putting  all  their  [investment]  eggs  in  one  basket".  In  addition,  successful 
CVCs  seem  more  capable  than  unsuccessful  CVCs  of  requiring  or  fostering  supplementary  business 
relationships  between  their  corporation  and  investment  ponfolio  firms.  By  exploiting  these  synergies, 
successful  CVCs  are  able  to  add  more  than  money  to  their  venture  investments.  Although  fostering 

16 


extensive  business  relationships  appears  vital  to  effective  CVC  performance,  exercising  excessive 
control  is  not,  as  is  indicated  by  the  fact  that  successful  CVCs  have  a  lower  fraction  of  investments  in 
which  they  either  manage  day-to-day  operations,  have  a  board  member,  exercise  board  control,  or 
have  the  abihty  of  replacing  the  venture's  CEO.  These  three  differences  in  managerial  approach  seem 
profound. 

FINANCIAL  SUCCESS  OF  CVC  PROGRAMS 

Much  of  the  earlier  literature  pointed  to  the  relationship  between  financial  success  of  venture 
programs  and  strategic  success  (Peterson,  1967;  Fast,  1981;  MacMillan  et  al.,  1985;  MacMillan  et  al., 
1987;  DeSarbo  et  al.,  1987;  Siegel  et  al.,  1988;  Sykes,  1990).  This  relationship  is  complicated  here 
because  our  data  are  subjective,  self-reponed  "facts".  Managers  may  convince  themselves  that 
financially  successful  ventures  were,  in  retrospect,  strategic.  Conversely,  corporations  will  rarely 
benefit  from  synergies  so  large  that  they  offset  the  poor  financial  performance  of  a  venture  program. 

Figure  1 1  shows  the  expected  positive  correlation  between  financial  and  strategic  success  of 
CVC  programs.  The  positive  relationship  between  financial  and  strategic  success  is  particularly  strong 
for  strategically  successful  firms.  This  strong  positive  relationship  for  strategically  successful  firms 
may  be  due  partly  to  managers  convincing  themselves  that  any  venture  that  makes  money  is  strategic. 
CVC  programs  that  are  well  positioned  strategically  are  also  successful  financially,  which  is  comforting 
to  top  managers  considering  launching  a  CVC  program. 

Yet  inferring  that  imposing  financial  objectives  on  a  CVC  program  will  yield  strategic  results  as 
some  previous  papers  have  suggested  ignores  the  cause-and-effect  relationships.  Managing  a  CVC 
program  primarily  for  financial  success  will  probably  produce  a  diversified  portfolio  of  ventures 
scattered  all  over  the  market-technology  familiarity  matrix  (see  Hardymon  et  al.,  1988)  with  few  of  the 
intra-venture  or  venuire-corporation  synergies  that  are  necessary  for  effective  corporate  growth 
(according  to  Roberts  and  Berry,  1985,  and  Roberts  and  Meyer  ,  1991). 

QUALITATIVE  ATTRIBUTES  IMPORTANT  TO  CVC  SUCCESS 

Asking  CVC  managers  to  provide  qualitative  factors  critical  to  their  CVC  program  success 

17 


might  have  brought  forth  a  list  of  their  own  CVC  attributes.  To  remove  this  bias  of  self-reported  data, 
CVCs  were  asked  which  three  firms  they  considered  good  at  making  direct  investments  in  small 
companies  and  why  they  consider  them  successful.  Table  6  shows  the  top  eight  corporations  regarded 
by  respondents  as  "good"  at  corporate  venturing.  Over  half  of  the  respondents  indicated  they  thought 
these  firms  were  successful  because  of  one  or  more  of  the  following  factors:  (1)  a  well-defined 
strategy,  with  focus,  clarity,  and  constancy  of  purpose;  and  (2)  well-organized,  with  independence  and 
support  from  top  management.  Because  strategic  focus  is  reported  to  be  a  driver  of  success,  financial 
performance  objectives  may  not  produce  strategically  successful  CVC  investments,  as  discussed  above. 

CONCLUSIONS 

The  strategies  of  49  large  U.S.  corporations  that  are  using  corporate  venture  capital  (CVC)  for 
new  business  development  were  studied  and  evaluated.  These  corporations  are  from  a  wide  range  of 
industries  and  are  thought  to  represent  the  broader  spectrum  of  CVCs.  The  strategies  of  more 
successful  firms  were  quantitatively  and  qualitatively  compared  with  those  of  less  successful  firms  to 
provide  insights  into  effective  CVC  strategies. 

1.  Venture  capital  firms  (VCs)  are  the  key  deal  source  for  CVCs  making 
strategically  successful  direct  investments  in  small  ventures. 

To  interact  effectively  with  VCs,  CVCs  should  directly  invest  in  VC  portfolio  fmns,  network 
with  VCs  without  necessarily  investing,  and  contact  VCs  holding  some  of  the  corporation's  pension 
assets.  As  an  entry  strategy,  CVCs  should  invest  in  VC  funds,  becoming  a  VCLP;  however,  being  a 
continuing  investor  in  VC  funds  is  not  necessary  in  the  long-run  for  generating  deal  flow. 

2.  Corporate  familiarity  with  the  venture's  market  is  more  important  in 
determining  strategic  success  than  familiarity  with  the  venture's  technology. 

CVCs  must  therefore  evaluate  a  venture's  market  with  greater  due  diligence  than  seems  typical 
in  current  practice.  Further,  corporations  should  seek  to  add  value  to  their  ventures  through  marketing 
expertise. 

3.  Strategically  successful  CVCs  make  more  investments  in  later  rounds,  as 
compared  with  less  successful  firms. 

18 


CVCs  should  either  make  more  later  round  investments  or  structure  early  round  investments  to 
increase  the  probability  of  strategic  success.  In  particular,  CVCs  should  not  exercise  excessive  conQ-ol 
over  their  portfolio  firms. 

4.  The  flnancial  performance  of  CVC  programs  is  positively  correlated  with 
strategic  success,  but  CVC  managers  report  that  strategic  success  results  from  a 
focussed  strategy. 

Therefore,  corporations  using  CVC  for  new  business  development  do  not  pay  a  financial  price 
for  the  program.  However,  if  the  corporation  is  seeking  to  develop  new  businesses  from  its  CVC 
program,  CVC  managers  should  not  have  their  compensation  based  solely  on  their  CVC  portfolio's 
financial  performance. 

Acknowledgement 

The  authors  appreciate  the  financial  sponsorship  of  this  work  by  Exxon  Chemical  Company.  Many  of 
the  analyses  performed  here  were  suggested  and/or  improved  by  Mark  Pratt  of  Exxon  Chemical. 


19 


REFERENCES 

Bams,  L.  June  25,1984.  Acquiring  the  expertise  but  not  the  company.  Business  Week  142B-142F. 
Block,  Z.  Fall  1983.  Can  corporate  venturing  succeed?  yowrwa/o/fiw^me^^  5rraregy  3(2):21-33. 
Block,  Z.  and  Omati,  O.A.  1987.  Compensating  corporate  venture  managers.  Journal  of  Business 

Venturing  2:41-51. 
Buderi,  R.  1990.  Can  small  companies  again  find  big  bucks?  fiw^me^^  W'ee/:    Special  Edition, 

Innovation:50-51. 
Bygrave,  W.D.  1988.  The  structure  of  investment  networks  of  venture  capital  firms.  Journal  of 

Business  Venturing  3:137-154. 
DeSarbo,  W.,  MacMillan,  I.C,  and  Day,  D.L.  1987.  Criteria  for  corporate  venturing:  importance 

assigned  by  managers.  Journal  of  Business  Venturing  2:329-350. 
Fast,  N.D.  March  1981.  Pitfalls  of  corporate  venturing.  Research  Management  21-24. 
Ford,  D.  and  Ryan,  C.  March-April  1981.  Taking  technology  to  market.  Harvard  Business  Review 

117-126. 
Gee,  E. A.  and  Tyler,  C.   1976.  Managing  Innovation.  New  York:  John  Wiley  &  Sons. 
Gibson,  W.D.  May  7,  1986.  A  maze  for  management:  choosing  the  right  technology.  Chemical  Week 

74-78. 
Golden,  W.J.  and  Rind,  K.W.   1984.  Venture  capital  as  a  corporate  development  tool.    In  Arthur  D. 

Little  Decision  Resources    Cambridge,  MA:Arthur  D.  Little. 
Greenthal,  R.P.  and  Larson,  J. A.  September-October  1982. Venturing  into  venture  capital.  Business 

Horizons  18-23. 
Hardymon,  G.F.,  Devino,  M.J.,  and  Salter,  M.S.  May-June  1983.  When  corporate  venture  capital 

doesn't  work.  Harvard  Business  Review  1 14-120. 
Hegg,  G.  L.  1990.  A  corporate  view  of  venture  capital.  In  Managing  R&D  Technology:  Building  the 

Necessary  Bridges    New  York:The  Conference  Board  28-30. 
Hlavacek,  J.D.,  Dovey,  B.D.,  and  Biondo,  J.J.  January-February  1977.  Tie  small  business 

technology  to  marketing  power.  Harvard  Business  Review  106-1 17. 
Levine,  J.  October  1983.  Corporations  eye  venture  gains.  VenrMre  124—126. 

20 


MacMillan,  I.C.,  Siegel,  R.,  and  SubbaNarasimha,  P.N.   1985.  Criteria  used  by  venture  capitalists  to 

evaluate  new  venture  proposals.  Journal  of  Business  Venturing    1 : 1 19-128. 
MacMillan,  I.C,  Zemann,  L.,  and  SubbaNarasimha,  P.N.   1987.  Criteria  distinguishing  unsuccessful 

ventures  in  the  venture  screening  process.  Journal  of  Business  Venturing  2:123-137. 
Peters,  T.J.  and  Waterman,  R.H.  1982.  In  Search  of  Excellence  New  York:Warner  Books. 
Peterson,  R.W.  May-June  1967.  New  venture  management  in  a  large  company.  Harvard  Business 

Review  68-76. 
Posner,  B.C.  June  1984.  Mutual  benefits:  Analog  Devices's  daring  strategy  for  coping  with  change 

has  led  to  unique  relationships  with  small  companies  around  the  country.  Inc.  82-92. 
Rind,  K.W.   1989.  Dealing  with  the  corporate  venture  capitalist.  In  J.K.  Morris  and  S.  Isenstein, 

eds.,  Pratt's  Guide  to  Venture  Capital  Sources,  thirteenth  edition  1 13-1 16. 
Rind,  K.W.  1981.  The  role  of  venture  capital  in  corporate  development.  Strategic  Management 

Journal   2:169-180. 
Rind,  K.W.  October  18,  1982.  Introduction  to  venture  capital.  The  Wall  Street  Transcript. 
Roberts,  E.B.  July-August  1980.  New  ventures  for  corporate  growth.  Harvard  Business  Review 

134-142. 
Roberts,  E.B.  and  Berry,  C.A.  Spring  1985.  Entering  new  businesses:  selecting  strategies  for 

success.  Sloan  Management  Review  3-17. 
Roberts,  E.B.  and  Meyer,  M.H.  Spring  1991.  Product  strategy  and  corporate  success.  IEEE 

Engineering  Management  Review    1 9(  1 ) :4- 1 8. 
Rumelt,  R.P.  1982.  Diversification  strategy  and  profitability.  Strategic  Management  Journal 

3:359-369. 
Selz,  M.  June  19,  1990.  RPM  bases  success  on  keeping  owners  of  firms  it  buys.  Wall  Street  Journal 

B2. 
Siegel,  R.,  Siegel,  E.,  and  MacMillan,  I.C.   1988.  Corporate  venture  capitalists:  autonomy,  obstacles, 

and  performance.  Journal  of  Business  Venturing    3(3):233-247. 
Slutsker,  G.  November  5,  1984.  Reaching  for  the  corporate  lifeline.  Forbes  118-127. 
Sykes,  H.B.  1990.  Corporate  venture  capital:  strategies  for  success.  Journal  of  Business  Venturing 

21 


5:37^7. 
Sykes,  H.B.  May-June  1986.  Lessons  from  a  new  ventures  program.  Harvard  Business  Review 

69-74. 
Sykes,  H.B.  and  Block,  Z.   1989.  Corporate  venturing  obstacles:  sources  and  solutions.    Journal  of 

Business  Venturing  4: 1 59-1 67. 
Weiss,  L.A.  Fall  1981.  Start-up  businesses:  a  comparison  of  diversification.5/oa;i  Management 

Review    37-53. 
White,  R.M.  March  20,  1989.  How  Control  Data  defines  and  buys  technologies.  Electronic  Business 

111-113. 
Winters,  T.E.  and  Murfm,  D.L.  Summer,  1988.  Venture  capital  investing  for  corporate  development 

objectives.  Journal  of  Business  Venturing  3(3):207-222. 
Zirger,  B.J.  and  Maidique,  M.A.  July  1990.  A  model  of  new  product  development:  an  empirical  test. 

Management  Science  36(7):  867-883. 


22 


LIST  OF  TABLES 

Table  1  Sources  of  Investment  Opportunities 

Table  2  Statistical  Comparison  of  Sources  of  Investment  Opportunities 

Table  3  Statistical  Comparison  of  Market  and  Technology  Diversification  Strategies 

Table  4  Comparison  of  Investment  Criteria  of  CVCs  and  VCs 

Table  5  Statistical  Comparison  of  Timing  of  Investments 

Table  6  Corporate  Venturers  Regarded  as  "Good"  at  Venturing  by  Other  Corporate  Venturers 


23 


TABLE  1.  SOURCES  OF  INVESTMENT  OPPORTUNITIES 


%  of  All  Investments  from  Source 

In-house  People 

32.0 

Venture  Capital  Firms 

28.2 

Unsolicited  Business  Plans 

17.0 

Investment  Bankers 

7.6 

University  Research  Programs 

5.8 

Consultants 

4.9 

Miscellaneous  Networking^ 

4.5 

100.0% 

"•"Primarily  at  conferences 


24 


TABLE  2.  STATISTICAL  COMPARISON  OF 
SOURCES  OF  INVESTMENT  OPPORTUNITIES 


Unaffilated  Venture  Capitalists*  All  Venture  Capitalists'* 

Critical  t-value+  2.06  L48 

(Successful-Unsuccessful) 

P++  0.025  0.10 


Universities  Primary  Source  Distribution 

(see  Figure  3) 
Critical  t-value  1.41  1.12 


p  0.10  0.15 

+  t-value  calculated  as  (mean  of  Successful-mean  of  Unsuccessful)/pooled  standard  deviation. 

Therefore,  positive  numbers  indicate  that  successful  firms  use  this  strategy  to  a  greater  extent,  negative 
values  indicate  that  successful  firms  use  this  strategy  less. 

"•■+        Probability  that  we  are  mistaken  in  believing  that  a  difference  between  successful  and 
unsuccessful  firms  exists,  based  on  a  one-sided  t-test.  Lower  values  indicate  greater  statistical 
significance. 

Unaffiliated  are  VC  funds  with  which  the  corporation  is  in  contact,  but  in  which  the  corporation 
has  not  invested  money,  i.e.  the  corporation  is  not  an  LP  of  the  VC. 

This  category  of  VCs  includes  all  deals  from  VCs. 

25 


TABLE  3.  STATISTICAL  COMPARISON  OF 
MARKET  AND  TECHNOLOGY  DIVERSIFICATION  STRATEGIES 


Market  Familiarity*       Technology  Familiarity 


25  Successful  Average:  2.90  3.40 

Std.  Dev.:  0.80  0.79 

24  Unsuccessful  Average:  3.33  3.44 

Std.  Dev.:  1.06  LIO 

Critical  t-value+  -L59  -0.13 
(Successful-Unsuccessful) 


0.50 


See  Figures  5  and  6  for  definition  of  market  and  technology  familiarity. 

"•"  t-value  calculated  as  (mean  of  Successful-mean  of  Unsuccessful)/pooled  standard  deviation. 

Therefore,  positive  numbers  indicate  that  successful  firms  use  this  strategy  to  a  greater  extent,  negative 
values  indicate  that  successful  firms  use  this  strategy  less. 

"•"•"        ProbabiUty  that  we  are  mistaken  in  believing  that  a  difference  between  successful  and 
unsuccessful  firms  exists,  based  on  a  one-sided  t-test.  Lower  values  indicate  greater  statistical 
significance. 


26 


TABLE  4.  COMPARISON  OF  INVESTMENT  CRITERIA  OF  CVCs  AND  VCs* 


Most  Frequently  Rated  Essential  %  CVC  %  VC 


Capable  of  sustained  effort 
Familiar  with  market 
Able  to  evaluate  and  react  well  to  risk 
Market/Industry  attractive  to  corporation 
Product  fits  with  corporation's  strategy 
Target  market  enjoys  high  growth  rate 
Product  can  be  protected 
Entrepreneur  demonstrated  leadership 
Return  lOX  investment  in  5-10  years 

Criteria  in  top  ten  for  VC,  but  not  CVC 

Articulate  in  discussing  venture 
Track  record  relevant  to  venture 
Investment  can  be  easily  made  liquid 


67 

64 

67 

62 

48 

NA 

39 

NA 

37 

NA 

35 

43 

31 

29 

31 

50 

28 

50 

8 

31 

5 

37 

0 

44 

*Source:Siegeletal.  (1988). 


27 


TABLE  5.  STATISTICAL  COMPARISON  OF  TIMING  OF  INVESTMENTS 


Zero/Seed  Stage 


First  Round  Investments 


Critical  t-value* 
(Successful-Unsuccessful) 


-2.17 


P-^ 


0.005 


0.02 


Second  Stage 


After  Initial  Public  Offering 


Critical  t-value 
(Successful-Unsuccessful) 


2.45 


1.84 


0.01 


0.05 


t-value  calculated  as  (mean  of  Successful-mean  of  Unsuccessful)/pooled  standard  deviation. 
Therefore,  positive  numbers  indicate  that  successful  firms  use  this  strategy  to  a  greater  extent,  negative 
values  indicate  that  successful  firms  use  this  strategy  less. 


■•"     Probability  that  we  are  mistaken  in  believing  that  a  difference  between  successful  and  unsuccessful 
firms  exists,  based  on  a  one-sided  t-test.  Lower  values  indicate  greater  statistical  significance. 

28 


TABLE  6.  CORPORATE  VENTURERS  REGARDED  AS  "GOOD"  AT  VENTURING 
BY  OTHER  CORPORATE  VENTURERS 


Corporation                %  of 

Respondent 

3M 

44 

DuPont 

15 

Eli  Lily 

13 

General  Electric 

13 

Coming 

10 

Hoffman-La  Roche 

10 

roM 

10 

Monsanto 

10 

29 


LIST  OF  FIGURES 

Figure  1      The  complex  processes  of  a  corporate  venture  capital  program. 

Figure  2     Examination  of  differences  in  average  deal  sources  of  successful  and  unsuccessful  firms 

indicates  that  successful  firms  use  venture  capitalists  as  a  deal  source  to  a  greater  extent 

Figure  3     Examination  of  differences  in  primary  deal  sources  of  successful  and  unsuccessful  firms 

indicates  that  successful  firms  use  venture  capitalists  as  a  deal  source  to  a  greater  extent. 

Figure  4     Diversification  is  harder  than  sticking-to-the-knitting  in  corporate  venture  capital  investing. 

Figure  5     Sticking-to-your-market  is  more  successful  than  diversifying.  Diversifying  in  the  market 

dimension  is  at  least  as  difficult  as  diversifying  in  the  technology  dimension  (see  Figure  6). 

Figure  6     Sticking-to-your-technology  is  more  successful  than  diversifying.  Diversifying  in  the 

market  dimension  is  at  least  as  difficult  as  diversifying  in  the  technology  dimension  (see  Figure  5). 

Figure  7     Investing  in  later  rounds  increases  the  likelihood  of  strategic  success. 

Figure  8     Investing  in  later  rounds  increases  the  likelihood  of  strategic  success,  independent  of 

diversification  strategies.  See  Figure  4  for  definition  of  "diversification". 

Figure  9      Similar  types  of  investment  structures  are  used  by  both  successful  and  unsuccessful  CVCs. 

Figure  10   Successful  CVCs  take  lower  initial  equity  positions,  develop  and  foster  supplementary 

business  relationships  more  effectively,  and  exercise  less  control  over  ventures  than  do  unsuccessful 

CVCs. 

Figure  1 1    Financial  and  strategic  success  are  positively  correlated,  particularly  for  strategically 

successful  CVC  programs. 


30 


Figure  1.  The  complex  processes  of  a  corporate  venture  capital  program. 


Dgveloping 
the  venlUTG 
program 


Establish  venture  goals  and  focus 
Fornnulate  venture  group  structure 
and  strategy 


nilialing  Uncover  investment  opportunities 

nvGEtrnGnts  Establish  investment  selection 

criteria 
Structure  and  make  investments 


Managing 

Assist  the  management  of 

the  investment 

individual  firms 

portfolio 

Foster  synergies  among  portfolio 

firms 

Help  determine  each  portfolio 

firm's  strategy 

A9£im11ating 

Establish  common  strategies 

invQEtmgnts 

among  firms 

Into  business 

Develop  significant  new  business 

group 

Transfer  venture  expertise  into 

core  businesses 

31 


Figure  2.  Examination  of  differences  in  average  deal  sources  of  successful  and 
unsuccessful  firms  indicates  that  successful  firms  use  venture  capitalists  as  a  deal 
source  to  a  greater  extent 


O 
a 
a 
O 


40 


30 


20  - 


^       10 


O 


Legend: 

^  25   successful    firms 
I    I  24   unsuccessful    firms 


fl 


^-       '•'\/-\.o<^' 


.<^ 


e"    ^      G° 


32 


Figure  3.  Examination  of  differences  in  primary  deal  sources  of  successful  and 
unsuccessful  firms  indicates  that  successful  firms  use  venture  capitalists  as  a  deal 
source  to  a  greater  extent. 


60 


■^      50 


c 

D 
+-• 

i_ 

o 
a 
a 
O 


40 


30 


20 


10 


O 


Legend: 

Wi  25   successful    firms 
□  24   insuccessful   firms 


^<?'  "?%<? 

y 


33 


Figure  4.  Diversification  is  harder  than  sticking-to-the-knitting  in  corporate  venture 
capital  investing. 


I- 
LU 

:^ 

< 


Different  5 


Similar  3 


Core    1 


W 


1  3  5 

Core  Similar  Different 

TECHNOLOGY 

COMPARISON    OF    OVERALL    STRATEGY 


Sticking 

-to- 
Knitting 

Diversification 

Legend 

1 

Number 

23 

26 

Success   Average 

3.696 

3.308 

Standard 
Deviation 

0 

82 

2 

0.736 

Comparative    t   value     1.521 


34 


Figure  5.    Sticking-to-your-market  is  more  successful  than  diversifying. 
Diversifying  in  the  market  dimension  is  at  least  as  difficult  as  diversifying  in  the 
technology  dimension  (see  Figure  6). 


I- 
LLI 

< 

2 


Different  5 

Similar  3 

y///////A 

'■z^zm, 

m/y/yy//, 

w/m 

1 

■ 

1 

Core    1 

mm 

■■mm 

'mmmm^ 

el 

1  3  5 

Core  Similar  Different 

TECHNOLOGY 

COMPARISON    OF    MARKET    STRATEGY 


Sticking 

-to- 
Market 

Diversification 

Legend 

1 

Number 

33 

16 

Success   Average 

3.576 

3.250 

Standard 
Deviation 

0 

79 

2 

0.683 

Comparative    t   value     1.216 


35 


Figure  6.     Sticking-to-your-technology  is  more  successful  than  diversifying. 
Diversifying  in  the  market  dimension  is  at  least  as  difficult  as  diversifying  in  the 
technology  dimension  (see  Figure  5). 


h- 
LJJ 

DC 
< 

2 


Different  5 


Similar  3 


Core    1 


1  3  5 

Core  Similar  Different 

TECHNOLOGY 

COMPARISON    OF    TECHNOLOGY    STRATEGY 


Sticking 

-to- 

Technology 

Diversification 

Legend 

n 

Number 

29 

20 

Success   Average 

3.759 

3.350 

Standard 
Deviation 

1 

43 

1 

0.745 

Comparative   t   value     1.272 


36 


Figure  7.    Investing  in  later  rounds  increases  the  likelihood  of  strategic  success. 


60 


50 


40   - 


30 


20 


10 


0 


Legend: 
r~l   25   successful 
24    uTSuccessful 


37 


Figure  8.    Investing  in  later  rounds  increases  the  likelihood  of  strategic  success, 
independent  of  diversification  strategies.  See  Figure  4  for  definition  of 
"diversification". 


60 


50 


40 


30 


20 


10 


0 


Legend: 
b||   Successful 
Unsuccessful 


^  J'  -S-* 


^^   ^°V 


«^^^ 


^> 


■y    ^-^ 


38 


Figure  9.    Similar  types  of  investment  structures  are  used  by  both  successful  and 
unsuccessful  CVCs. 


70 
60 
50 
40 
30 
20 
10 
O 


m 


Legend: 

H   14    successful 

I    I  8   unsuccessful 


^e^ 


o-    X) 


s<Z^ 


x<^ 


39 


Figure  10.    Successful  CVCs  take  lower  initial  equity  positions,  develop  and  foster 
supplementary  business  relationships  more  effectively,  and  exercise  less  control  over 
ventures  than  do  unsuccessful  CVCs. 


80 

70 

60 

50 

40  h 

30 

20 

10 


O 


Legend: 

H   14    successful 

I    I  8   unsuccessful 


M 


J^^    ^-^->o^ 


o-    O^V^ 


^* 


40 


Figure  11.    Financial  and  strategic  success  are  positively  correlated,  particularly  for 
strategically  successful  CVC  programs. 


0) 
(/) 
(D 
U 
U 
D 

00 


u 

c 

c 

LL 

0) 
D) 

03 

i— 

0) 
> 

< 


4 


O 


• 

/ 

/ 
/ 
/ 

] 

H 

• 

t/ 

c 

^      i 

3 

-- 

21 

f 

5 

19 

LEGEND: 

_            □   Category    Avg. 

No. 

Number   of    Firms    in   Category 
1                1                1 

Strategic    Success    Rating 


41 


MIT   LIBRARIES    DUPl 


lllllillililllii 
3    TDflD    0D75abbl    D 


Date  Due  ?-^-f  z^ 


JAN.  0  2  1934' 


3    TOflO  DD7Sflhbl  0