Skip to main content

Full text of "Inventory level as a signal to a middleman with imperfect information"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

AT  URBANA  CHAMPAIGN 

BOOKSTACKS 


Faculty  Working  Papers 


INVENTORY  LEVEL  AS  A  SIGNAL  TO 
A  MIDDLEMAN  WITH  IMPERFECT  INFORMATION 

Masanao  Aoki 


#231 


College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 

University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPERS 
College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 
February  10,  1975 


INVENTORY  LEVEL  AS  A  SIGNAL  TO 
A  MIDDLEMAN  WITH  IMPERFECT  INFORMATION 

lias  an ao  Aoki 

#231 


INVENTORY  LEVEL  AS  A  SIGNAL  TO 
A  MIDDLEMAN  WITH  IMPERFECT  INFORMATION*" 


by 


Mas ana o  Aoki 

Department  of  Economics  and  Electrical  Engineering 

University  of  Illinois 

Urbana,  Illinois 


+ 
A  preliminary  version  of  this  paper  has  been  presented  at  the  49th 

Annual  Conference  of  the  Western  Economic  Association,  Las  Vegas, 

Nevada,  June,  1974,  as  "A  Pricing  Policy  of  a  Middleman  Under  Imperfect 

Information",  by  Masanao  Aoki  and  Steven  Sworder. 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2012  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/inventorylevelas231aoki 


1.   Introduction 

A  great  deal  of  attention  has  recently  been  paid  to  raicroeconomic  aspects 
of  decision-making  by  economic  agen.s  under  incomplete  information.   See 
i.7~*  10^]     Q**A   U^-J,  Leijonhufvud,  for  example,  considered  a 

quantity  adjustment  model  derived  from  the  Marshallian  homeostat  [6],   In  [6] 
the  good  is  assumed  perishable  and  the  aspect  of  inventory  holding  has  not  been 
discussed.  With  no  inventory  (by  assuming  that  the  goods  are  nonstorable) , 
decision-making  processes  of  economic  agents  are  sufficiently  different  from 
those  in  which  inventories  are  held,  and  in  a  sense  simpler. 

In  an  economy  of  uncertain  and  imperfect  information,  however,  ex  ante 
plans  of  households  and  firms  will  not  be  generally  coordinated.  What  they 
plan  are  not  what  they  end  up  doing.   In  such  an  economy,  one  expects  inventor-f^'- 
to  play  an  important  role  as  buffer  against  the  consequences  of  mismatched 
plans.—   Inventory  holding  behavior  of  a  store-keeper  or  a  middleman  in  the 
world  of  uncertain  and  incomplete  information  has  not  been  analyzed  to  any 
extent.   See  however  [1,8], 

In  this  paper,  one  model  of  a  middleman  who  holds  inventory  is  posited  in 
Section  2  and  his  pricing  behavior  is  examined  under  imperfect  information  assump- 
tions.  One  thing  this  middleman  knows  with  certainty  is  a  fact  that  he  is  one  of 
the  many  middlemen  selling  a  homogeneous  good  or  some  close  substitutes.   He 
does  not  know  exactly  the  current  prices  other  middlemen  are  charging.  This 
may  be  due  to  cost  involved  in  gathering  this  piece  of  information  and /or  due 
to  time  involved  in  obtaining  the  price  estimates  which  may  make  the  estimates 
somewhat  obsolete.   We  denote  the  middleman's  price  by  p  and  some  index  of  the 
"market"  prices  by  p.   This  middleman  observes  his  sales  i.e.,  how  fast  his 
inventory  is  being  depleted  weekly  (monthly  or  quarterly)  in  response  to  the 


-2- 
price  he  sets  and  to  exogenous  disturbances  which  he  cannot  observe  directly. 
In  other  words,  in  our  model  the  price  is  the  decision  variable  and  the  middle- 
man's sales,  i.e.,  the  quantities  sold,  or  equivalently  the  level  of  inventory 
and  changes  in  the  level  of  inventory  constitute  the  only  direct  signals  he 
receives,  either  to  confirm  or  to  refute  some  or  all  of  his  subjectively  held 
beliefs  about  the  market  he  is  in  and  the  demand  conditions  he  faces. 

The  signal  he  observes  mixes  two  kinds  of  messages,  one  being  the  feed- 
back from  his  setting  of  price  and  the  other  originating  from  exogenous  sources 
(random  shifts  of  product  demand,  for  example)  and  occuring  independently  of 
his  decision.   This  complicates  his  decision  process  either  to  confirm  or 
to  refute   some    or  all  of  his  subjectively  held  beliefs  about  the  market 
he  is  in  and  the  demand  condition  he  faces.   He  must,  if  he  can,  unscramble 
these  two  types  of  information  since  his  appropriate  response  to  the  two 
kinds  of  events  would  be  different.   For  example,  an  observed  decline  in  his 
own  sales  over  a  succession  of  'weeks'  might  mean  either  of  two  things.   It  could 
mean  that  competitors  have  lowered  the  prices  they  charge  so  that  his  own 
price  is  now  out  of  line  with  prices  prevailing  elsewhere  in  the  market;  if 
this  were  the  case,  unless  he  lowers  his  price,  he  would  be  threatened  by  a 
continuing  loss  of  customers  to  other  sellers  as  consumers  continue  to  learn 
about  the  prevailing  price  distribution.   On  the  other  hand,  it  could  mean 
that  market  demand  has  declined  generally  with  all  sellers  losing  sales 
in  roughly  the  same  proportion  —  a  less  alarming  situation. 

Our  question,  then,  is  whether  he  will  be  able  to  unscramble  these  two 
types  of  information  in  the  signal  he  receives  from  the  market,  and  respond 
properly  to  these  two  different  types  of  information.   In  particular  we  examine 
if  the  middleman  is  able  to  "track"  changes  in  the  "price  prevailing  elsewhere" 
in  the  market.   To  examine  a  possible  situation  in  which  the  question  may  be 


-3- 

answered  affirmatively,  we  assume  that  amount,  q,  purchased  by  a  customer 
arriving  at  his  store  is  random  and  and  is  governed  by  a  probability  distri- 
bution function,  which  is  taken  to  be  a  Gamma  distribution  F(q;a,u).   The 
parameters,  a  and  u,  which  distinguish  one  Gamma  distribution  from  the  others 
are  postulated  to  vary  with  the  price  differential,  p  -  p"  causing  relative 
shifts  of  demands  and  with  the  exogenous  parameter  G,  indicating  general  shifts 
in  demand.   The  precise  nature  of  these  dependence  is  described  in  Sec  2  . 
The  technique  is  independent  of  the  specific  distribution  function,  namely 
of  the  assumption  of  the  Gamma  distribution  and  is  applicable  to  a  wider  class 

of  distributions. 

The  price  the  middleman  sets  to  maximize  his  long  run  profit  rate  depends 

crucially  on  two  quantity  signals  and  their  price  elasticities:   on  the  average 
rate  of  sale  per  week,  the  deviation  of  his  storage  cost  from  the  "average  cost" 
to  be  specified  later,  and  their  subjectively  conceived  price  elasticities. 
Another  important  factor  is  the  customer  arrival  rate  (which  affects  the  rate 
of  sales  per  week)  and  its  price  elasticities.   The  pricing  behavior  of  the 
middleman  turns  out  to  be  the  same  whether  customer  arrivals  are  modelled  as 
a  Poisson  process  or  a  uniform  stream.   We  consequently  perform  the  major  part 
of  our  analysis  of  the  implications  of  the  posited  dependent  of  the  r(q;a,u) 
on  p  -  p  using  a  stream  of  customers  arriving  at  a  uniform  rate.   Point  pro- 
cesses such  as  a  Poisson  process  can  also  be  used.   They  affect  the  analysis 
only  through  the  average  number  of  customers  (which  affects  the  average  sales 
per  week)  and  its  price  elasticity.   We  assume  that  the  information  on  price 
differentials  spreads  only  gradually  among  customers  so  that  in  the  short  run 
the  rate  of  arrivals  is  not  affected  by  the  price  differentials.  We  indicate 
in  Sec.  5  how  this  assumption  may  be  relaxed. 


After  establishing  the  method  of  discriminating  between  general  and  rela- 
tive shifts,  we  examine  auxiliary  questions  of  how  to  detect  parameter  shifts 
and  modify  estimates  of  cx,u  and  the  arrival  rate  parameter.   Since  these  are 
statistical  in  nature  and  a  body  of  literature  exists  on  detection,  we  only 
briefly  suggest  a  way  these  parameter  values  could  be  monitored. 

2.   Model 

Consider  a  middleman  who  sells  a  storabie  consumption  good,  cans  of 

2/ 
soups,  say.—   He  faces  a  stream  of  customers,  each  of  whom  buys  a  random 

amount  of  the  good.   The  distribution  function  which  probabilistically 
governs  demand  by  a  customer  is  assumed  to  come  from  a  class  of  distribution 
functions  known  to   the  middleman.   The  value  of  the  parameter  vector,  which 
specifies  a  distribution  function  in  the  class  completely,  is  unknown  and  de- 
pends on  the  price  p  the  middleman  sets  and  on  prices  of  goods  which 
are  close  substitutes  in  the  market,  as  well  as  on  some  exogenous  parameters, 

We  shall  refer  to  these  prices  loosely  as  prices  prevailing  elsewhere 
in  the  market.   We  use  f>   to  denote  some  index  of  these  prices. 

The  exogenous  parameter  may  represent  for  example,  random  shifts  of  de- 
mands for  the  good  and  its  close  substitutes.   We  may  think  of  the  middleman 

selling  a  slightly  product  differentiated  good  and  trying  to  establish  the 

3/ 
right  amount  of  price  difference.—   A  customer  is  Indifferent  then  from 

whom  he  purchases  the  good,  if  the  price  is  the  same  after  allowance  for 

whatever  product  differentiation  is  made. 

Once  the  middleman  sets  a  price  p,  he  must  decide  either  to  maintain 

p  or  to  change  p  in  the  fact  of  fluctuating  demands  he  experiences  over 

4/ 
time.—   Fluctuations  in  the  sales  the  middleman  observes  is  partly  due  to 

the  stochastic  nature  of  demand  for  the  good,  partly  due  to  exogenous  random 

shifts,  if  any,  of  demands,  and  of  course  partly  due  to  the  fact  that  the 


-5- 

price  differences  p-p  is  not  generally  zero.   The  amount  purchased  by  a 
customer,  once  he  arrives  at  his  store,  responds  without  delay  to  the  exist- 
ing price  differential  p-p,  through  the  assumed  dependence  of  the  parameters 
of  the  distribution  on  it.   Customer  arrivals  respond  to  price  changes  by 
gradual  learning,  hence  do  not  change  instantaneously.   It  is  important  to 
realize  that  the  value  of  0  and  the  p-p  differential  are  not  directly 

observable.   It  is  revealed  indirectly  through  the  quantity  signals  the 

5/ 
middleman  receives.   Customers  are  assumed  to  arrive  at  a  constant  rate.— 

Once  a  customer  arrives  at  a  store,  he  purchases  a  random 
quantity  q  >  0  of  the  good.   We  assume  q  to  be  a  continuous  variable.— 
Let  g(q;9,p,p)  be  its  probability  density  function  which  is  assumed 
to  exist.   (We  drop  6,  p  and  p  from  g(q;...).)   One  example  of  g(0 
is  the  T-distribution.   Its  probability  density  function  is 


,  Na-1  -uq 


where  a  and  y  are  the  parameters  of  the  distribution,   a  is  known  as  the 
shape  parameter,  and  y  is  called  the  scale  parameter.   They  depend  on  p,  p 

and  0  also.   Their  dependence  on  p,  p  and  9  will  be  made  explicit  later. 

2 
The  mean  is  given  by  a/y  and  the  variance  Is  a/y*".   These  parameter  values 

are  not  known  precisely  to  the  middleman.   We  discuss  a  possible  scheme 

for  estimation  and  update  of  these  parameters  later  in  Section  3.  We  make 

an  inessential  assumption  that  a  is  a  positive  integer  to  facilitate 

analytical  manipulations  carried  out  in  Appendix  1. 

The  middleman  is  assumed  to  be  rational  in  that  he  sets  p  so  as  to 

maximize  "average"  profit  over  some  long  time  interval. 


-6- 
The  average  profit  rate  tt  is  aken  to  be  given 

it  =  R  -  C  (2) 

where  R  is  the  average  revenue  rate  from  sales  and  where  C  is  the  cost  (rate) 

composed  of  set-up  costs  and  the  storage  cost.   To  focus  our  attention  on  the 

stochastic  demand  side,  assume  that  he  can  get  instant  delivery  of  the  supply 

of  the  good  for  any  amount,  with  a  constant  set-up  cost  5  per  delivery  and 

that  he  always  replenishes  his  stock  to  the  level  of  Q  as  soon  as  the  stock 

7/ 
is  depleted.—   A  storage  cost  (rate)  d  proportional  to  the  level  of  inven- 
tory is  charged  each  instant  of  time.   Denoting  by  c  the  unit  cost  he  pays 
to  the  factory,  we  have 

it  =  (p  -  c)  x  average  quantity  sold  'per  week' 

-  5  x  average  number  of  reorders  'per  week'  -  d  *  'weekly' 

average  stock  level.  (2*) 

As  indicated  in  Section  1,  we  are  interested  in  the  decision  problem 
of  the  middleman.   His  decision  problem  is  made  more  difficult  because  of 
the  random  amount  of  purchases  made  by  individual  customers.   We  now  formulate 
his  problem  as  a  sequential  statistical  decision  problem  of  when  to  conclude 
that  p-p  ^  0  or  the  value  of  9  has  changed,  i.e.,  when  to  decide  that  his 
price  is  out  of  line  with  the  price  prevailing  in  the  market  and  when  to 
decide  that  a  changing  trend  in  the  amounts  sold  is  due  to  change  in  the 
demand  for  the  goods  due  to  shift  in  preference  and  so  on. 

As  a  first  approximation  to  this  problem,  suppose  that  exogenous  change 
in  the  demand  (shift  in  the  preference)  entails  that  every  customer's 
purchase  is  changed  by  the  same  but  unknown  amount,  6%,  while  p-p  i   0 
changes  a   and  y  in  such  a  way  that  customers  who  normally  have  large  demand 


-7- 

8/ 
are  affected  more  Chan  customers  with  normally  small  demand.—   This  shall 

be  made  precise  shortly.  Suppose  that  when  there  is  an  exogenous  shift  in 

the  demand  schedule  then  each  customer  buys  y  -  (1  +  0)x  Instead  of x . 

6-0  corresponds  to  the  situation  before  the  shift.   The  amount  of  purchase 

now  is  governed  by  the  probability  density  function 


iW  .  vta£V 


(a) 


where 


T+V  ' 


Namely ,  the  scale  parameter  \i   is  changed  to  y/1+8,  while  the  shape  parameter 
a  remains  the  same.  In  other  words,  the  general  shift  in  demand  can  be 
detected  as  a  shift  in  the  mean  with  no  change  in  coefficient  of  variation 
defined  as 

c2(x)  .  Var^  f 

[E(x)r 

since  the  mean  changes  by  (1+6)  from  -  to  -(1+6)  but  the  standard 
deviation  also  increases  by  the  same  proportion  from  /a/y  to  /$.[  (1+6  )/y]. 
Suppose  now  the  price  the  middleman  charges  is  low  compared  with  the 

A 

price  prevailing  elsewhere  in  the  market,  p  <  p.  Then  those  who  have  larger 
demands  (and  those  whose  budget  allows  larger  purchases)  will  buy  larger 

A 

amounts  to  stock  up.  If  p  >  p,  however,  those  who  would  be  normally 
buyers  of  large  amounts  sharply  curtail  their  purchases  more  than  those 


! 


-8- 
vith  smaller  demands. 

Keeping  our  example  of  cans  of  soups  in  mind,  we  model  the  type  of 
purchasing  pattern  which  is  sensitive  to  price  differentials  by  positing: 


q(p)  -  q(p)  +  e(p-9)q(p)C,  (3) 


where 


>  0,  p-p  <  0 
\   =  0,  p-J  -  0  (31) 

<  0,  p-p  >  0  , 

and  where  |e(p-p)|   is  small  for  small   |p-p|. 

Such  a  form  may  be  justified  by  considering  a  customer  whose  utility 
function  is  given  by 


U  =  (  ql  +  q2  )q3       0<Y.3<1, 


where  good  1  and  good  2  are  close  substitutes.  The  total  number  of  goods 
need  not  be  three.  This  is  chosen  polely  for  ease  of  illustration. 

By  maximizing  D  subject  to  his  budget  constraint,  I-p-q.+p^q^+p^q^j ,  the 
demand  for  good  1  is  given  by 


A-i-i 


q^const.p"1^  +  !2-  **) 


with  a  similar  expression  for  q„.  In  other  words,  if  the  price  difference 
Pj-Pi  between  the  substitutes  is  small,  then 


'  '  ■ 


-9- 


q^q^l+Cp^p^/CY-DpJ 

t3q1+e(p2-P1)qi  +  °(e> 


where 


e(P2-P1)::  -2(y  +  6)(p2-Pl)/  (l-Y)Yl 


This  is  a  special  case  of  (3)  with  E  =«  2. 
Eq. (3)  leads  to  the  expression  of  the  mean  and  the  variance  of  purchase, 

m(p)-m(p)  +  e(p-p)L  (4A) 

where 

L-E(qC)  r(a+C)/r(a)uC  >  0, 
and 

V(p)-V(p)  +  2eLC/y.  (4B) 

2 
When  C  "2,  L«a(a  +  l)/p  . 

From  these,  combining  the  effec  s  of  exogenous  shifts,  discussed  earlier, 
we  postulate  that  the  parameters  of  the  distribution  approximately  vary  with 
p  as 

a(p)  =  a(p)(l  +  g(p-£))2(1  +  2ce(p-J))~1  (AC) 

y(p)  2  P(p)d  +  e(p-p))(l  +  2ce(p-p))"1(l  +  9)"1 
for   | p-p |    small , 
or  equivalently 

m(p)  ^mCpMl  +  e(p-$))(l  +  8) 

and  (4D) 

v(P)  -  v(?)(i  +  2e(P-p))(i  +  e)2 


-10- 


where  we  rename,  for  simplicity. 

e(p-p)L/m(p) 

as  e(p-p).  Since  L  and  m(p)  are  both  positive  the  properties  (3*)  still 
hold. 

Eq(4C)(or  (4D))  is  basic  to  our  model  of  the  middleman's  decision 
problem. 

It  follows  from  (4C  or  D),  then,  that  the  middleman  can  monitor  three 
sets  of  parameter  combinations  in  order  to  determine  whether  or  not  a  shift 
in  the  demand  schedule  has  occurred  or  his  price  is  out  of  line  with  the 
"prevailing"  price,  i.e.,  there  are  three  mutually  exclusive  cases  he  can 
distinguish: 

Case  1.  If  the  mean,  ot/u,  of  the  demand  distribution  changes 
and  a  does  not,  then  6  (the  demand  shift  parameter) 
has  changed. 
Case  2.  If  a  or  the  coefficient  of  variation  changes,  then  the  asking 

price  is  not  equal  to  the  market  price. 
Case  3.  If  both  the  mean  and  the  coefficient  of  variation 
change,  then  6  has  changed  and  the  price  is  not 
equal  to  market  price, 
The  problem  is  that  of  detection  or  statistical  hypothesis  testing.  A 
number  of  standard  techniques  have  been  developed  and  are  available  in 
statistical  and/or  communicating  engineering  literature.  We  briefly  return 
to  this  topic,  after  ve  resolve  the  optimal  pricing  problem  for  the 
middleman. 


-11 

3.     Optimal  prices 

The  middleman  sets  his  price  to  maximize  TT  of  (2').  We  show  in 
Appendix  1  that  under  the  assumption  that  Q  is  much  greater  than  the 
average  purchase  a/y,  we  have 

TT  -   (p-c)A  -  6A/Q  -  d(2  +  S)  +  ocVq)  (5) 

where 

A  -  pm  is  the  average  quantity  sold   'per  week' ,   p  is  the   (average) 
customer  arrival  rate,  m  ■  a/y 

A/Q  is  the  average  number  of  reorders   'per  week' 

and 

|  +  S  is  the  average  stock  level.  In  Appendix  1  ,  it  is  shown 


that 


s  - !  -  h  (6) 


where  k  -  0(1). 

In  the  above,  dQ/2  is  the  cost  of  storage  'per  week'  if  the  quantity  Q 

is  sold  at  a  constant  rate.   So  lon^  as  Q  is  fixed,  it  is  a  fixed  cost  in- 
dependent of  prices.   There  is  a  correction  term,  ds,  to  the  average  cost 

of  storage  due  to  the  fact  that  customers  do  not  buy  same  quantities  and 

only  a  finite  number  of  them  arrive  per  period.  S  is  not  zero  even  if 

the  same  number  of  customers  are  assumed  to  arrive  at  the  store  at  a 

uniform  rate,  so  long  as  they  do  not  buy  the  same  quantity.  Thus,  S^O 

reflects  in  an  essential  way  the  random  purchase  assumption  of  this  model. 

From  (5),  the  first  order  condition  for  the  maximization  of  the  profit 

rate  is 

p._  c .  m .  _  a  +  d « ; 


-12- 
where  *  denotes  the  derivative  with  respect  to  p,  p*  is  the  optimal 
price  —  and  where 


i1 
m 


Let 


and 


A'/A-  p»/p  +5  .  (8) 


e=-81nA/81np, 


f= — 31ns/  31np  :  the  price  induced  ratio  of 

%  change  in  s  over  %  change  in  A. 

Substituting  these  into  (6),  we  obtain  the  expression  for  p* 

p*  -  (c  +  6/Q  +  df S/A)  / (1-1/e) . 
In  the  above  expression  for  the  optimal  price,  ds/A  is  the  ratio  of  the 
storage  cost  deviation  (from  the  weekly  average  storage  cost)  over  the 
average  weekly  sales.  Higher  this  ratio,  higher  p*.  When  everybody 
purchases  a  same  quantity,  then  it  disappears  completely.  The  expression 
(1-1/e)  shows  that  higher  e,  lower  p*. 
The  maximum  average  profit  is 

7T*  -  -dQ/2  +  {(c  +  6/Q)A/(e-l)}  +  dS  (—;  -1). 

An  exogenous  shift  0  changes  the  last  two  terms  of  the  above,  i.e.,  the  part 
of  the  profit  dependent  on  p  changes  to 


{(c  +  6/Q)A/(e-l)  +  ds(|Sj-l^   (1  +  6). 


Thus,  if  the  middleman  has  chosen  Q  at  which  it*  is  zero,  then  0  >  0  now 
makes  his  average  profit  positive  and  0  <  0  would  make  it  negative. 

In  evaluating  e  and  f ,  we  need  price  eleaticities  of  a,  V,  s  and  P . 
At  the  end  of  Section  2  we  posited  (4).  From  these  relations  we  can  obtain 


-13- 
the  needed  price  elasticities  of  them. 

We  assume  p'  =  0.   In  other  words,  the  knowledge  that  the  middleman's 
price  is  different  from  the  price  prevailing  in  the  market  does  not  spread 
instantaneously  hence  does  not  affect  in  the  short  run  the  rate  at  which  the 
customers  come  to  him. — '  See  Section  5   for  the  discussion  of  p  *  ?*  0. 
Combining  the  expressions  for  m' /m  and  y'/u  from  (AD)  into  (6)  and  (7),  we 
obtain  the  expression  for  the  middleman's  price  when  he  is  in  line  with  p  as 


'-*  — '"-pferfc^W. 


(8) 


since 


A' /A-       £,<Pi>       =       gtW *_  (9) 

A  /A        l+e(p-p)  14€»<0><p-g>     '  k  } 


and 


^-■^(l  -  fcW  -  *?  +  *W  '  9  e(p  -  gj.  (10) 

for  | p— p |  small,  where  a  -  a(p). 

Change  in  p 

The  right  hand  side  of  (7)  together  with  (9)  and  (10)  enables  the 
middleman  to  follow  p  when  it  changes  under  mild  conditions  on  the  assumed 
manner  by  which  the  distribution  of  q  is  sensitive  to  price  differentials. 
We  state  this  as 


-14- 
Proposltlon 

Suppose  p  shifts  to  a  new  value  and  stays  at  the  new  value.  Then 
the  middleman  following  the  price  equation  (7)  can  eventually  restore  the 
price  differential  to  zero,  if 


d(2C-l)ke'(0) 


2p  a(p) 


<  1 


(11) 


See  proof  in  Appendix  2. 

The  condition  of  convergence  (11),  rewritten  as 


WI*'<o>l<:nf£?fr. 


d(2C  -  1) 

shows  that  the  price  sensitive  behavior  of  the  quantity  purchased  can't  be 
too  great,  otherwise  the  middleman  tends  to  overcorrect.   It  also  shows 
that  higher  the  storage  cost  more  unstable  the  price  correction  behavior 
is  likely  to  be  for  the  same  |e'(0)|.   In  other  words,  the  higher  d,  the 
smaller   |e'(0)j  must  be  for  this  price  adjustment  method  to  be  stable. 
The  more  frequently  customers  arrive,  the  higher  e*(0)  could  be. 

In  the  special  case  of  £  -  2,  (11)  becomes  (recalling  that  Le/m  is 
renamed  as  e  in  (A)) 


ke'(O) 


3d  (a  +  1)    3d  V(Ji) 


(12) 


showing  that  a  smaller  value  of  the  ratio  of  m/V  requires  a  smaller  value 
of  |e'(0)|  for  stable  adjustments.   In  other  words,  as  variability  of 
individual's  purchase  become  larger,  less  sensitive  the  quantity 


-15- 
purchased  must  be  to  price  differential  for  the  middleman  to  adjust  his 
prices  successfully* 

Change  in  8 

When  the  price  difference  is  zero,  the  middleman's  price  is  given  by 
(8).   In  (8),  none  of  the  terms  will  change  when  general  shifts  in  demand 
occur  since  we  assume  that  p  is  not  affected  by  6  in  this  model  in  the  short 
run. 

Thus  we  have 

Proposition 

The  optimal  price  of  the  middleman  is  the  same  for  6  j*  0  in  the  short 
run.  This  may  be  seen  also  directly  from  the  expression  for  the  long  run 
profit  (5).  In  (5),  the  portion  of  ir  that  is  price  sensitive  (i.e.,  all 
terms  except  -dQ/2)  is  affected  equally  by  (1+0). 

4.  Parameter  Estimates  and  Their  Revisions 

Obviously  the  price  that  the  middleman  sets  is  strongly  dependent  on 
his  beliefs  about  the  customer  arrival  rate,  the  parameters  of  the  demand 
schedule  and  their  elasticities.  Because  the  parameters  are  not  known 
perfectly  and  are  subject  to  change  without  his  knowledge,  the  middleman 
must  estimate  them  and  be  prepared  to  revise  his  beliefs  in  the  face  of 
contradiction  with  observed  data. 

The  statistical  problem  he  faces  is,  first  of  all,  that  of  hypothesis 
testing  and  secondly  that  of  parameter  estimation:   he  must  decide  to  keep 
his  current  beliefs  (point  estimates)  of  the  parameters  or  decide  to  reject 
them  and  revise  his  beliefs  (substitute  new  point  estimates). 


-16- 

Since  he  can  resort  only  to  statistical  processing  of  the  sales 
records  he  possesses  to  arrive  at  whatever  conclusions  such  as  he  must 
revise  his  estimates  of  the  parameters  or  the  sales  data  he  has  does  not 
refute  his  currently  held  estimates  and  so  on,  he  will  need  sales  records 
involving  large  number  of  customers  to  reduce  the  probabilities  of  wrong 
decisions. —  The  higher  the  rate  of  customer  arrivals,  the  better  he  is  able  to 
cope  with  shorter  run  phenomena.  However,  it  would  place  an  unreasonable 
computational  burden  on  the  middleman  to  require  him  to  update  his  parameter 
estimates  after  each  customer.  Even  if  he  did  update  them  that  often  it 
is  highly  unlikely  that  he  would  want  to  continually  vary  his  prices  based 
on  the  considerations  of  information  cost  and  of  the  reliability  of  his 
decisions.  We  thus  assume  that  all  the  observed  data  is  pooled  from  the 
time  of  his  most  recent  price  change. 

The  hypothesis  is  that  his  current  beliefs  are  correct.  The  alternate 
hypothesis  is  that  they  are  wrong.   Such  a  test  is  called  composite 
hypothesis  testing  in  the  statistical  literature.  It  is  known  that  the 
likelihood  ratio  test  has  optimal  asymptotic  properties  under  some  regularity 
conditions  which  are  also  sufficient  for  the  existence  of  asymptotically 
normally  distributed  maximum  likelihood  estimates,  and  in  many  cases  has 
optimal  properties  for  finite  samples  as  well.  Further  it  i6  known  that 
the  logarithm  of  the  likelihood  ratio  asymptotically  has  the  chi-square 
distribution  and  the  maximum  likelihood  estimates  asymptotically  coincide 
with  the  maximum  chi-square  estimates,  see  Cramer,  Wilkes.   Since  the 
maximum  likelihood  estimates  for  the  parameters  of  Gamma  distributions  are 
asymptotically  normally  distributed  and  asymptotically  efficient,  a  simple 


-17- 

test  that  the  middleman  can  perform  to  determine  whether  or  not  his 
beliefs  are  correct  Is  to  use  chl-square  estimates  of  the  parameters  and 
use  the  table  to  accept  or  reject  the  hypothesis,  or  more  simply  to  monitor 
the  maximum  likelihood  estimate  of  each  parameter  and  to  reject  his  belief 
In  any  parameter  estimate  which  escapes  from  a  band  of  width  3  three  standard 
deviations  (given  In  the  previous  asymptotic  normal  distributions)  on  each 
side  of  his  current  belief  in  the  parameter  value.   If  a  parameter  value 
Is  rejected  then  the  current  maximum  likelihood  estimate  of  that  parameter 
is  assumed  to  be  the  correct  value.  This  new  parameter  value  is  then 
tested  in  the  manner  just  described. 

See  Appendix  for  the  expression  of  the  maximum  likelihood  estimates. 

5.  Conclusion  and  Discussion 

The  paper  shows  the  importance  of  the  inventory  level  in  a  model  of 
a  middleman  in  which  random  quantity  purchase  by  individual  customers  is 
explicitly  modelled.  In  other  words  quantity  purchased  varies  from  customers 
to  customers.  The  probability  distribution  of  quantity  purchased  is  then 
assumed  to  change  with  price. 

The  pricing  behavior  of  the  middleman  remains  the  same  when  the 
customers  are  assumed  to  arrive  as  a  Poisson  process.  This  complicates 
the  computation  of  the  average  inventory  level  somewhat.   Its  expression 
is  the  same  up  to  0(1/4). 

The  condition  (11)  or  (12)  shows  that  the  middleman  need  not  know  the 
parameters  a,  u  and  p  exactly  so  long  as  they  satisfy  the  indicated  in- 
equality for  him  to  be  able  to  "track'1  p  eventually. 


-18- 

For  simplifying  the  exposition  we  assume  p'  -   0  in  this  paper.  As 
indicated  in  the  main  body  of  the  paper  this  does  not  change  the  formula 
for  p*  since  p'  enters  into  p*  only  through  A' /A  where  A  is  the  average 
sales  'per  week'.   It  is  a  simple  matter  to  include  a  test  for  p  a  constant. 
To  consider  the  price-induced  change  in  p,  however,  it  is  more  realistic  to 
model  the  customer  arrival  as  a  stochastic  process  such  as  a  Poisson  process 
and  incorporate  another  hypothesis  test  for  p  »  constant.   It  is  possible 
to  give  more  structure  to  price-sensitive  behavior  of  p  by  modelling  the 
gradual  spread  of  price  information  explicitly.  See  for  example  Phelps 
and  Winter  in  Phelps,  for  one  such  model. 

How  might  he  know  that  theories  or  beliefs  he  holds  above  the  economy 
are  being  systematically  refuted  by  messages  or  signals  they  receive?  This 
paper  formulates  this  question  as  a  sequential  hypothesis  testing  problem 
and  illustrates  the  formulation  in  some  detail  for  a  middleman  with  inventory 
of  nonperishable  consumption  goods.   Even  though  the  details  of  discussions 
may  be  specific  to  this  simple  example,  the  outline  of  analysis  Indicated 
in  this  paper  is  believed  to  be  usefv  L  in  c  broader  coniext.  For  example, 
the  idea  of  using  price  dependent  parameters  to  model  the  collective 
behavior  of  consumers  may  find  applications  in  other  areas. 

Acknowledgement 

The  author  wishes  to  acknowledge  help  from  A.  Leijonhufvud  and  an 
ancjymous  referee  both  of  whom  contributed  much  to  make  the  paper  readable. 


-19- 


Footnotes 


1.  The  roj.e  of  buffer  stocks  in  Ktynesian  models  has  been  discussed 
by  Leijonhufvud,  [5]. 

2.  This  example  ha-  been  suggested  by  A.  Leijonhufvud. 

3.  Instead  of  assuming  that:  gathering  and  processing  information  related 
to  p  is  costly  and/Ci  tine  consuming,  we  may  assume  that  the  middleman 
is  a  new  entrant  to  the  market  or  has  just  introduced  a  new  line  of 
goods  or  opened  a  new  store.  The  author  owes  this  interpretation  to 

M.  Nabli.  We  do  not  however  discuss  the  aspect  of  entry  to  the  market, 
assuming  the  market  is  closed  to  new  entry. 

4.  An  alternate  possibility  is  to  assume  that  a  customer  has  the 
probability  a  of  purchasing  a  unit  of  the  good  and  the  probability 
1-a  of  not  purchasing  the  good.  Sunh   a  model  may  be  appropriate  when 
the  good  in  question  is  a  durable  or  capital  good.  The  kinds  of  goods 
that  fit  our  modal  would  be  s.ore  in  the  nature  of  nonperishable  con- 
sumer goods,  cans  of  soups  for  example. 

5.  Customer  arrivals  can  be  modeled  as  a  stochastic  point  process,  for 
example,  a  Poisson  process. 

6.  The  explicit  adoption  of  redistributions  as  the  demand  distribution 
of  an  individual  customer  is  not  cruical  for  the  purpose  of  analysis 
in  this  prjper.  Its  use  permits  us  to  derive  explicit  expressions  for 
such  items  as  the  averrge  cost  of  storage,  etc.  as  functions  of  the 
location  ar.d  scale  parameters  of  the  demand  curve  which  facilitates 
seme  comparative  static  analytic c   besides,  the  use  of  the 
F-di^rribution  is  not  very  r<sf  "rictive,  appropriate  choice  of  the 
location  and  scale  p'rncatnr*  permit  a  wide  range  of  possible  shapes 
of  the  demand  distribution  to  be  approximated. 

7.  He  follows  thersfcre  (s,S)  policy  where  s=0  SEQ.  here  s  may  be 
taken  to  be  zero  due  to  the  instrntaneous  delivery  assumption. 
Given  five .  .u'  :ing  demands;  he  will  attribute  the  demand  variation 

in  part  to  hie  price  being  net  in  11ns  with  the  average  market  price 
and  in  part  attribute  the  variation  to  the  exogenous  change  in  the 
economic  conditions.  How  this  is  done  is  outlined  later  in  the  paper. 
He  would  generally  change  both  Q  and  the  price  p.  In  this  paper, 
we  focus  attnetion  to  the  pricing  scheme  while  holding  Q  fixed. 

8.  This  has  been  suggested  by  A.  Leijonhufvud. 


-20- 


9.  Note  that  the  price  induced  change  in  the  customer  arrival  rates 
appear  in  p*  only  through  A' /A.,  i.e.,  as  the  changes  in  the  average 
sales  'par  week'.   It  is  therefore  of  no  great  less  of  generality 
to  assume  p"  =»  0  in  the  short  ri  ».  and  assume  A'  /A  to  be  entirely 
due  to  m?/m, 

10.  See  footnote  9. 

11.  There  are  two  ty?es  of  errors;  concluding  erroneously  that 
revision  is  called  for  and  the  error  of  not  detecting  changes  in 
the  parameter  values.  When  the  sample  is  small,  he  will  not  be 
able  to  make  decisions  with  anv  reliability.   In  ether  words,  he 
will  not  be  able  to  catch  very  transient  or  temporary  fluctuations 
in  0,  for  example. 


•21- 


Refercnces 


1.  M.  Aoki,  "On  a  Dual  Control  Approach  to  Pricing  ~  elides  cf  a  Trading 
Specialists"  in  Goo::  (ed)  Lecture  Notes  In  Computer  Science  No.  4 
5th  Conference  en  Optimization  Techniques,  Part  II,  272-282, 
Springer  Verlag  1973, 

2.  D.  R.  Cok,  Renewal  Theory*  John  Wiley  £md  Sons,  Inc.,  New  York,  1962. 

3.  D.  R.  Cox  and  P.  A,  W.  Lewis,  "The  Statistical  Melyslu  of  Series  of 
Events,"  Msthuen  and  Company,  Ltd.,  London,  1366. 

4.  H.  Cramer,  "Mathematical  Methods  of  Statistics,"  Princeton  Unvicrsity 
•   Press,  19 46. 

5.  Axel  Lei'onhufvud,  "Effective  Demand  Failure,"  Swedish  Econ.  Journal, 
March  1973.  pp.  27-48. 

6.  Axel  Leijonhufvud,  "The  Varieties  of  Price  Theory:  What  ilicrofounda- 
tions  for  Macrotheory,"  Discussion  Paper  No.  44,  Department  of 
Economics ,  UCLA,  January  197'',. 

7.  R.  E.  Lucao,  Jr.5  and  E.  C.  P res cot t,  "Investment  Under  Uncertainty," 
Ecorcetrica,  39,  (5),  659-681,  September,  1971. 

8.  E.  S.  Phelps,  et.  al. ,  Eicrcoconomic Foundations  of   Eapl'.-vr.^nt  and 
Inflation  Theory,  !".  7.  T  :rton  am!  Company.,  Inc.,  New  York,  1970.. 

9-   Michael  Rothschild,,  "Models  of  Market  Organisation  with  Imperfect 
Information!  A  Survey,"  JPE,  81,  No.  6,  1283-1308,  Nov/  I  :  1973. 

10.  Herbert  E.  Scarf,  Dorothy  II,  Gilford,  and  M.  W.  Shelly  ad.  ,  Multistat 
Inventory  Models  and  Techniques,  Stanford  University  Press,  1963. 

11.  Saras!  S.  Wilks,  Mather.? tical_ .Static tics ,  John  Wiley  and  Sens,  Inc., 
1962. 

12.  S.  Grossman,  "Rational  Expectations  and  the  Econometric  1 'ode ling  of 
Markets  Subject  to  Uncertainty:  A  Bayesian  Approach,"  University  of 
Chicago,  Department  of  3cor.cric3,  Working  Paper ,  November f  1973. 


Appendix  I 

Derivation  of  the  Long  Pom  Profit  Function 

To  obtain  the  long  run  average  expression  of  tt,  as  defined  by  (2f), 
we  need  compute  the  three  terms  in  (2').  They  are  3tated  as  Lemma  1,  2  and 
3.  We  assume  that  customers  arrive  at  the  middleman's  store  at  a  uniform 
rate  of  P  customers  'per  week'. 

Let  T  be  the  random  variable  denoting  the  time  interval  (weeks) 
between  reorder  and  let  N  be  the  number  of  customers  (random  variable) 
between  reorder. 

By  definition 

pE(TQ)  -  E(NQ). 


Lemma  1 


s<v--£  ♦a5r1+»<Q>- 


Note  that 


where 


2a     ,  2 

2m 


E  -  E(q),  and     V  ■  Var  (q) 


Proof 


Let  q.  be  the  quantity  purchases  by  the  1-th  customer. 
Then,  denoting  probability  event3  by  [   ],  we  have 


r-1 


[N  =  r]   <*— ^    [J£J  c ,  <  Q  <  F±m±   q±]  , 


and 


A-2 
where 

t££i  «±  <  Q  <    rtml  ^1  -  Igj  «i  <  Q.  -a  Q  i  EI.!  q±l 

and  where 

These  two  events  on  the  right-hand  side  are  mutually  exclusive,  hence 

Hll~l   q±  <  Q  <  1^  qj  -  Kr-1(Q)  -  Kr(Q)  (A.l) 

where 

Kr(Q)  =  *ll\ml   q±  <  Ql,  r  -  1,  2,  ...  (A.2) 

KQ(Q)  =  1    ,   Q  >  0  . 

We  have 

E<y  -  Co r  P[NQ  s  r] 

85  Co  r(Kr-l(Q)  '  Kr(Q)? 

"  Co  Kr(Q)"  (A*3) 

We  assume  the  series  is  absolutely  convergent. 

We  can  compute  K  (Q)  defined  in  (A.2)  by  the  Laplace  transform. 

From  the  assumption,  q.  are  independently  and  identically  distributed 
with  the  probability  density  function  g(q).     Denote  its  Laplace  transform 
by  g(s).    Then  the  Laplace  transform  of  the  density  £*   q.  is  [§(s)]  . 


A- 3 


By  definition,   g(s)   is   given  b* 


rco 


g(s;6) 


-sq  ,  a  a-1  -yq    . 
e         y  q        e   ^'  dq 


T(a) 


a 


y/(y  +  s)   ,     s  <+  y. 


Denote  the  Laplace  transform  of  K  (Q)  by  K  (s) .  We  have 


K  (a)  -  I  f-£- 
rN    s  \y  +  s. 


ar 


(A.4) 


From  (A. 3)  and  (A.4),  the  Laplace  transform  of  E(N0)  s  £[E(N0)]  is  given  by 


L[E0O3  =-f 


U-a+*raJ 


We  assume  a  to  be  a  positive  integer  so  that  this  is  a  rational  function. 
An  asympotic  expression  of  the  above  for  large  Q  can  be  obtained  by 
expanding  the  above  as  the  Laurent  series  expansion  in  s, 


IE(NQ)  -  H 


+  0LLi  1+0(1) 


s2    2y    s 


We  can  obtain  E(N_)  from  the  above  by  taking  its  inverse  Laplace  transform 


E(Nft) 


a 


Q  + 


a  +  1 
2y 


+  0(1) 


(A.  5) 


A-4 

Using  the  similar  technique,  we  can  establish 
Fact 


Var(TQ)  <  oo. 


Lemma  2 


The  average  number  of  reorder  per  week  is  1/E(T  ). 

Proof 

Consider  a  large  number  M  of  reorders.   It  spans  the  period  of 

T,  +  T„  +  ...  +  T,  where  T,  is  the  time  interval  of  i-th  reorder.  Each  T. 
1    2  M       i  i 

is  independently  and  identically  distributed  with  T_  discussed  above.   Thus 
by  the  Kolmogorov's  3trong  law  of  large  numbers. 


M 


7M         ~  E(T  )       a.s. 


Lemma  3 


The  average  stock  level,   Ss   is  given  by 


ECS)   «  Q  -f  fE(NQ)   -il  (A. 6) 


2  +    4y      +  °   [t\\ 


Proof 


We  establish 


E(S|NQ  «  r)   =  Q  -  I  (r-1) 


Then  (A. 6)   follows  immediately. 


A-5 
The  average  stock  level  is  by  definition 

S  ■  (time  integral  of  the  stock)  /  T  . 
Whenr  customers  arrived  in  one  cycle,  then 

S  -  [Q  +  (Q  -  6X)  +  ...  +  (Q  -  21r"1q±)  /r 

E(S|N  -r)-Q-m(l+2+...+  r-l)/r 

-Q-f(r-l), 

where  the  approximation  consists  in  replacing 

E(qil  3*^^  <  Q)  by  E(q±)  =  m. 

We  can  check  goodness  of  this  approximation  by  computing  E(S)  in  an  alternate 
way. 

Consider  a  large  number  N  of  re-order  cycles.  Let  T.  and  3.  be  the 
duration  and  the  time  integral  of  the  inventory  of  the  i-th  cycle.  The 
average  inventory,  then,  is  given  by  the  limit  of  I  ,  where 

where  T.  are  independently  and  identically  distributed.   The  random  variable 

S.  is  also  i.i.d 

Let 

S  "   ES . 

i 

T  ■  ET     ,  i  =  1,  ... ,  n. 


(A. 7)  is  expressible  as 


A-6 


I„  - 


S  +  Xj.1  (St  -  S)/N 


N  ■=  .    rN 


T  +  llml    (T±  -  T)/N 


s1  +  sn  lLi(srs) 

TN 


By  the  Kologorov's  strong  law  of  large  numbers,  we  have 

N  ^l-l(Si"?)  "*  °     a'S*    asN+a>' 
and 

k  J?  i  (T.-T)  ->  0     a.s.    as  N  ■*  «. 
N  Li=l  i 


Thus 


I„  *  S/T     a.s. 

N 


From  Lemma  1,  we  know  that 


T=  >+sl?+    «(«»• 


We  next  compute  S. 

Suppose  NQ  =  r.  Then  the  time  integral  of  the  inventory  is 

S  -  ±   [Q  +  (Q-qx)  +  ...  +  {QrZi'\)) 


A- 7 


Assume  Q  »  1  so  that 


Then 


Thus 


Erq1|q1  <  Q)   -  E(qx)   +  op) 
-  ct/u  +  o(l), 

E(ql  +  q2  ql+<12  <  Q)   "  ^  +  °(1/Q)      etC' 


E(S|NQ  -  r)  --|[rQ  -  2  (1  +  2  +  ...  +  r-1)]  +  o(l) 
-±[rQ-2^-]+o<l). 


S  -  E(S)  =  i[r  Q  2  -  ^f^-  ]  +  o(l) 


2         oo         o 
We  can  compute  r     =  IT     «  r 


(w»-v<» 


analogously  to  our  computation  of  r  In  Lemma  1, 

2 


^lF  =  ©  V+^Q+^+od). 

a     6a 


and 


r  -  ©Q  +  *£  +  o(l) 


La 


2a 


Substituting  these,  we  obtain 


«T      U     n2   .   q-1  „,       1-a  ,1% 

pSas2^Q     +1^Q-  12^    +  °(1)' 


or 


A-8 


E(s):2+fli  +  J[2a2%21I+0{1/Q).  (A.8) 


*      24  u2 


Comparing  (A. 6)  with  (A. 8),  we  see  that  these  expressions  differ 
by  0(1)  since  they  employ  different  approximations.   It  is  reassuring 
that  they  both  agree  on  the  leading  term,  however.  We  denote  the  average 
stock  level  then,  as 
Proposition 

E(S)  -f  [1  +fj|+  o(l/Q)] 

where  K  -  0(1). 

In  other  words,  the  average  stock  level  is  approximately  Q/2  as  expected 
since  the  stock  level  f luctuate  between  0  and  Q  and  a  correction  factor 
depending  on  the  average  amount  of  purchase  per  customer  a/y  and  on  Q. 


B-l 

Appendix  2 

When  the  middleman  is  at  equilibrium  with  the  'prevailing'  market 
price,  his  price  is  given  by  (8)  01  writing  a   for  ct(p) , 


A      6*   d  (   i   (2C  -  l)k  ]     1 


(0) 


Suppose  the  price  prevailing  elsewhere  in  the  market  changes  from  p  top' 
Take  this  to  have  occurred  at  time  0.   Since  the  reference  price  has 

shifted  from  p  to  p,  the  middleman  notices  this  as  changes  in  s'/A'  and 

in  m/m' . 

At  time  1   (in  an  appropriate  time  unit  the  middleman  uses  to  revise 

his  prices  such  as  a  week,   a  month  and  so  forth),   the  middleman's  price 

becomes  from  (8),    (9)  and   (10), 

Px  "  P  -  *(£  -  P 


where 


m  ,  _  d<2^  -  1)  ke 
A       X  2pa(p') 


In  general,  after  t  'weeks'  of  price  adjustment,  the  middleman  notices 
that  his  estimate  of  a  and  y  are  still  not  correct  and  adjust  his  price  by 


Pffl  =  Pt-  X(Pt-p,) 


P  ■  P 
o 


This  adjustment  equation  converges  to 


si 


limp  ■  p 

provided  |l  -  Xj  <  1  or 

d(2C-  Dkl£'(Q)| 

2pa(pAl)      i* 


C-l 


APPENDIX  3 
Maximum  Likelihood  Estimates  and  Asymptotic  Distributions 

We  summarize  some  useful  facts  on  the  maximum  likelihood  estimates 
for  easy  reference. 


Assume  the  estimation  is  to  be  based  on  the  observations  of  n 
customers.  The  demand  density  is  assumed  to  have  a  Gamma  distribution  . 


The  likelihood  function  is 


n 
-ui_qi 


L(q,p,cO  =  u^n  q,a-Xe  1^/rn(a) 
i=l  x 


na  "    a-1 


Taking  the  In  of  it  and  maximizing  it  with  respect  to  the  desired 
parameters  yields  the  maximum  likelihood  estimates, 


a  /—  T  q.-  , 
n.*\Mi  * 


where 


a     is  the  solution  to 


log  a     -    ijKa)     -  In  i  £q.     +    i  £  In  q±  -  0  i 


C-2 
and  where  we  define 


\Jj(a)  =  -r-  *n  T(a)  = 


da  *■"  iva/    Tea) 


Asymptotically      ij>(a)  «  £n  6.     -  ^  -  — -y  +  o(  —  ) 

12&       6t 

If  a  is  large  enough  then  a  is  the  solution  to 


1  K'        1    n 

4  -  ^n  -i  +  i   £n  q.  =  0 
2a        n     n  *•   ^-l 


or 

a  = 


2nto  g^qi  -  i  to^q.]  . 


Cox  and  Lewis  £pl37,33  show  that  the  sample  coefficient  of  variation 
is  an  asymptotically  efficient  estimator  of  a  as  a  becomes  large. 
It  is  a  simplier  and  consequently  perhaps  more  desirable  estimate  of  a. 


< h  V 


n  &i  "  (  FT  hi1' 


Continuing  with  the  other  maximum  likelihood  estimates 


n 

m 


n  J     qi 

n  i=l  x 


i=l 


/vie 

a 


C-3 


Finding  the  expected  value  of  q  of  the  second  derivate  of  the 
log  likelihood  function  leads  to  the  expression  for  the  variance  of 
the  asymptotic  normal  distribution  of  the  parameter  estimates  (Wilks, 
Cramer) , 


a  ~  N 


a, 


|   n[tK(a)~]j 


and 


y  "   N 


Via)] 


where  ^»(a)  =  —•  ip(a)  *i+-l+-l-+0(4- 

2a   6a 


a  '  ~2  T  ~  T  OK   T  } 


a 


Note  that 


'i' 


Var  (y)  -  lH- 
n 


an 


We  see  that  Var(y)  is  independent  of  a  up  to  o(  — -  ) .  Thus  for  an 


an 
-2 


of  the  order  1CT,  then  Var(y) 2  is  of  the  order  10  .  Thus  for  all 

practical  purposes,  the  width  of  the  estimation  confidence  interval  may 
be  taken  to  be  independent  of  a. 


r-94