Skip to main content

Full text of "Investigation of concentration of economic power; monograph no. 1[-43]"

See other formats


-^ 


m^^ 


Given  By 
U.  S.  SUFl^    Or   DOCUlwfENTS 


^ 


^^3d  SessfJn^*}        SENATE  COMMITTEE  PRINT 

INVESTIGATION  OF  CONCENTRATION 
OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


TEMPOEAKY  NATIONAL  ECONOMIC 
COMMITTEE 

A  STUDY  MADE  UNDER  THE  AUSPICES  OF  THE  DEPART- 
MENT OF  COMMERCE  FOR  THE  TEMPORARY  NATIONAL 
ECONOMIC    COMMITTEE,    SEVENTY-SIXTH    CONGRESS, 
THIRD   SESSION,   PURSUANT   TO   PUBLIC   RESOLUTION 
NO.    113    (SEVENTY-FIFTH    CONGRESS),    AUTHORIZING 
AND   DIRECTING  A   SELECT   COMMITTEE   TO   MAKE   A 
FULL    AND    COMPLETE    STUDY    AND    INVESTIGATION 
WITH  RESPECT  TO  THE  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC 
POWER  IN,  AND  FINANCIAL  CONTROL  OVER, 
PRODUCTION  AND  DISTRIBUTION 
OF  GOODS  AND  SERVICES 


MONOGRAPH  No.  9 
TAXATION  OF  CORPORATE  ENTERPRISE 


Printed  for  the  use  of  the 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee 


^^i5  ^'o^?^®^^!         SENATE  COMMITTEE  PRINT 
3d  Session     J 


INVESTIGATION  OF  CONCENTRATION 
OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


IK  TEMPOEARY  NATIONAL  ECONOMIC 
COMMITTEE 

A  STUDY  MADE  UNDER  THE  AUSPICES  OF  THE  DEPART- 
MENT OF  COMMERCE  FOR  THE  TEMPORARY  NATIONAL 
ECONOMIC    COMMITTEE,    SEVENTY-SIXTH    CONGRESS, 
THIRD  SESSION,  PURSUANT  TO  PUBLIC  RESOLUTION 
NO.   113    (SEVENTY-FIFTH   CONGRESS),  AUTHORIZING 
AND  DIRECTING  A  SELECT  COMMITTEE  TO  MAKE  A 
FULL   AND   COMPLETE    STUDY   AND    INVESTIGATION 
WITH  RESPECT  TO  THE  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC 
POWER  IN,  AND  FINANCIAL  CONTROL  OVER, 
PRODUCTION  AND  DISTRIBUTION 
OF  GOODS  AND  SERVICES 


MONOGRAPH  No.  9 
TAXATION  OF  CORPORATE  ENTERPRISE 


Printed  for  the  use  of  the 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee 


w 


UNITED  STATES 

GOVERNMENT  PRINTING  OFFICE 

WASHINGTON  :  1941 


FEB  2    1942       >^.^ 


TEMPORARY  NATIONAL  ECONOMIC  COMMITTEE 

(Created  pursuant  to  Public  Res.  113,  75th  Cong.) 

JOSEPH  C.  O'MAHONEY,  Senator  from  Wyoming,  Chairman 
HATTON  W.  SUMMERS,  Representative  from  Texas,  Vice  Chairman 
WILLIAM.  H.  KING,  Senator  from  Utah 
WALLACE  H.  WHITE,  Jr.,  Senator  from  Maine 
CLYDE  WILLIAMS,  Representative  from  Missouri 
B.  CARROLL  REECE,  Representative  from  Tennessee 
THURMAN  W.  ARNOLD,  Assistant  Attorney  General 
•WENDELL  BERGE,  Special  Assistant  to  the  Attorney  General 
Representing  the  Department  of  Justice 
JEROME  N.  FRANK,  Chairman 
*SUMNER  T.  PIKE,  Commissioner 
Representing  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission 
GARLAND  S.  FERGUSON,  Commissioner 

*EWIN  L.  DAVIS,  Chairman 

Representing  the  Federal  Trade  Commission 

IS  AD  OR  LUBIN,  Commissioner  of  Labor  Statistics 

•A.  FORD  HINRICHS,  Chief  Economist,  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics 

Representing  the  Department  of  Labor 

JOSEPH  J.  O'CONNELL,  Jr.,  Special  Assistant  to  the  General  Counsel 

♦CHARLES  L.  KADES,  Special  Assistant  to  the  General  Counsel 

Representing  the  Department  of  the  Treasury 


Representing  the  Department  of  Commerce 

LEON  HENDERSON,  Economic  Coordinator 
DEWEY  ANDERSON,  Executive  Secretary 
THEODORE  J.  KREPS,  Economic  Adviser 
•Alternates 


Monograph  No.  9 
TAXATION  OF  CORPORATE  ENTERPRISE 


n 


,OLJF^pRp  J..«PYNNIN^; 


..  Jh^Whti^  credit  ae&t, . 


ACKxNOWLEDGMENT 

This  monograph  was  written  by 

CLIFFORD  J.  HYNNING 

Department  of  Commerce 

in  consultation  with 

GERHARD  COLM 

Professor  of  Economics,  New  School  for  Social  Research 

Assisted  by 

JOSHUA  H.   HOLLAND,  HELEN  TARASOV,  JOHN  COPELAND,  FRED 
KONEMANN,  ELDON  SWEEZY,  AND  BETTY  BARNARD 

The  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  is  greatly  indebted 
to  these  authors  for  this  contribution  to  the  literature  of  the  subject 
under  review. 

The  status  of  the  materials  in  this  volume  is  precisely  the  same  as  that  of 
other  carefully  prepared  testimony  when  given  by  individual  witnesses;  it  is 
information  submitted  for  Committee  deliberation.  No  matter  what  the 
official  capacity  of  the  witness  or  author  may  be,  the  publication  of  his 
testimony,  report,  or  monograph  by  the  Cow.mittee  in  no  way  signifies  nor 
implies  assent  to,  or  approval  of,  any  of  the  fads,  opinions,  or  recommenda- 
tions, nor  acceptance  thereof  in  whole  or  in  part  by  the  members  of  the 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  individually  or  collectively. 
Sole  and  undivided  responsibility  for  every  statement  in  such  testimony, 
reports,  or  monographs  rests  entirely  upon  the  respective  authors. 

(Signed)     Joseph  C.  O'Mahoney, 
Chairman,  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee. 

m 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


Fas* 
Letter  of  transmittal xi 

CHAPTER  I 

The  problems  of  inquiry: 

Authorization  of  the  study 1 

Scope  of  the  stud}^ 2 

Taxes,  public  receipts,  and  governmental  expenditures 4 

Federal  taxation  of  corporate  profits 6 

Definition  of  corporate  profit  for  tax  purposes 13 

i\Iagnitude  of  Federal  taxes  and  corporate  profits,  1916-37 17 

CHAPTER  II 

Federal  taxation  of  corporate  income:  Statutory  rates,  exemptions,  and 
deductions: 

Industries  exempt  from  Federal  taxation  of  corporate  i  ncome 21 

Statutory  exemption  of  minimum  net  income 23 

Statutory  rate  structures 25 

Deductions  from  corporate  gross  income 2S 

Definition  of  the  accounting  period:  Deduction  of  prior  years'  losses.  3& 

CHAPTER  III 

Federal  tax  treatment  of  holding  companies  and  related  forms  of  intercor- 
porate affiliation  (consolidated  returns) : 

The  corporate  world 39 

Consolidated  corporate  income-tax  returns:  Origin  and  history 41 

(a)   Mandatory  consolidation 41 

(6)   Optional  consolidation 42 

(c)   Abolition  of  consolidated  returns  in  1934 44 

Importance  of  consolidated  returns,  1928-33 45 

Deduction  of  losses  by  subsidiaries 48 

Abolition  of  consolidated  tax  returns  in  1934 49 

CHAPTER  IV 

Intercorporate  dividends  and  interest  on  governmental  securities : 

Federal  taxation  of  intercorporate  dividends — history 53 

Magnitude  of  the  tax  credit  for  intercorporate  dividends,  1926-37,  by 

corporate  size  and  industries 56 

Corporate  investment  in  government  securities 63 

CHAPTER  V 

Federal  taxation  of  "excess  profits"  and  undistributed  profits  of  corpora- 
tions: 

Excess-profits  tax:  Premium  on  the  predictability  of  corporate  profits.         67 
Surtax  on  undistributed  profits :  Premium  on  the  distribution  of  cor- 
porate profits 70 

CHAPTER  VI 

Federal  corporate   income   taxes  paid  by  corporations  of  varying  size, 

1931-37 _• 81 

CHAPTER  VII 

Federal  taxation  of  monopoly  profits:  A  negative  record 87 

V 


VI  TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 

CHAPTER  VIII 

Page 
Equity  versus  creditor  capital  in  Federal  corporate  income  taxation 91 

CHAPTER  IX 

Variable-cost  taxes: 

Pay-roll  taxes 97 

Federal  excise  taxes 101 

State  sales  and  gross-income  taxes 105 

CHAPTER  X 

Fixed-cost  taxes: 

Property  taxes 109 

Business-privilege  and  license  taxes 110 

CHAPTER  XI 

Conclusions 115 

Federal  corporate-income  taxes  in  general 116 

Normal  corporate-income  tax 117 

Capital  stock  and  excess-profits  tax 118 

Undistributed-profits  tax 118 

Pay-roll  taxes 119 

Other  taxes 119 

APPENDIX  A 

War-excess-profits  taxation 121 

APPENDIX  B 

Federal  capital  stock  and  excess-profits  taxes 126 

APPENDIX  c 

Oliphant's  statement  on  history  of  undistributed-profits  problem 130 

APPENDIX  D 

Tax  experience  of  312  identical  manufacturing  corporations,  1934-37 132 

APPENDIX  E 

Sources  and  methodology 134 

APPENDIX  F 

Technical  tables 146 


SCHEDULE  OF  TABLES  AND  CHARTS 

TABLES 

Page 

I.  Sources  of  Federal  revenue,  1930-40 8 

II.  Federal  corporate  income  taxation,    1909-40;  amount  of  tax, 

statutory  and  effective  rates,  and  specific  credits 10-11 

III.  Deductions  and  credits  from  corporate  gross  receipts,  1917-37--    14-15 

IV.  Importance  of  consolidated  income-tax  returns,  1928-33 45 

V.   Magnitude  of  intercorporate  dividends,  1935-37 63 

VI.  Estimated  distribution  of  tax-exempt  securities  bv  classes  of 

holders,  June  30,  1937 64 

VII.  Types  of  dividends  distributed  by  corporations  subject  to  the 

surtax  on  undistributed  profits,  1936-37 77 

VIII,  Number  of  corporations  and  amount  of  net  before  interest  of 
591  manufacturing  and  trade  corporations  in  1937  tax  sample, 

by  profit  rate  classes 90 

IX.  Federal  taxes  on  manufacturing  industries,  1938 103 

X.  Federal  excise  and  State  sales  taxes  as  percent  of  sales  of  362 

manufacturing  and  trade  corporations,  1934-37 103-04 

XL  State  sales  taxes  as  percent  of  sales,  1936 106-07 

XII.  State  corporate  taxes  as  percent  of  gross  margin,  by  profit  rate 

classes  and  industries,  1937 112-13 

CHARTS 

I.  Changing  revenue  sources  of  Federal,  State,  and  local  govern- 
ments, 1913-38 5 

II.  Federal  corporate  income  taxes  and  corporate  gross  and  net 

incomes,   1909-37 Faces  13 

III.  Federal  taxes  and  corporate  income  available  for  reinvestment 

or  distribution  to  individuals,  1916-37 18 

IV.  Effect  of  1932  abolition  of  minimum  income  exemption  by  size 

classes  and  major  industries Faces  24 

V.  Statutory  deductions  from  corporate  receipts  by  size  classes, 

1937 29 

VI.  Interest  paid  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts,  by  size  classes  and 

industries,  1936 Faces  30 

VII.  Depreciation  and  depletion  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts,  by 

size  classes  and  industries,  1936 - —         32 

VIII.  Cumulative    effect    of    statutory    deductions    from    corporate 

receipts,  by  size  classes  and  industries,   1936 —  Faces  35 

IX.  Deduction  of  prior  years'  losses  as  percent  of  taxable  net  income, 

by  industries,   1926-32 ----  Faces  38 

X.  Deduction  of  prior  years'  losses  as  percent  of  taxable  net  income 

by  size  classes  and  industries,  1931-32 Faces  38 

XI.  Role  of  consolidated  returns  in  Federal  corporate  income  taxa- 

tion, 1929  and  1933 47 

XII.  Gross  and  net  income  on  consolidated  corporation  income-tax 

returns  as  percents  of  incomes  of  all  returns  by  industries, 
1928-33 Faces  49 

XIII.  Effect  of  abolition  of  consolidated  tax  returns  in  1934  on  cor- 

porate taxable  net  income  by  industries ^ 51 

XIV.  Federal  corporate  income  tax  pavments  and  special  credits  from 

net  income,  by  industries,   1926-37 Faces  56 

XV.  Federal  (normal)  corporate  income-tax  payments  as  percent  of 

profits  of  corporations  of  varying  size,  1931-37 58 

XVI.  Federal  (normal)  corporate  income-tax  payments  and  credits  for 

investment  income,  by  size  classes  and  industries,  1937 60-62 


VIII  SCHEDULE  OF  TABLES  AND  CHARTS 

CHARTS — continued 

Page 

XVII.   Federal   (normal)    corporate  income-tax  payments  and  credits 

for  investment  income,  by  minor  industries,  1937 Faces  62 

XVIII.  Interlocking  operation  of  Federal  capital  stock  tax  and  excess- 
profits  tax;  excess-profits  and  capital  stock  taxes  on  cor- 
porations of  varying  size,  1933-37 Faces  69 

XIX.  Federal  excess-profits  tax  payments  of  corporations  of  varying 

size  classes  and  industries,  1937 71 

XX.  Federal  excess-profits  tax  and   undistributed  profits-tax  pay- 
ments, cash  dividends  paid  out,  and  credits  for  investment 

income,  by  minor  industries,  1937 Faces  71 

XXI.  Federal  surtax  on  undistributed  profits  of  corporations,  by  size 

classes  and  manufacturing  industries,  1937 Faces  77 

XXII.  Federal  taxes  and  corporate  income  paid  out  as  cash  dividends 
or  available  for  reinvestment  or  industrial  replacement  by 
small,  medium-sized,  large,  and  giant  corporations,  1931-37- _  83 

XXIII.  Federal  corporate  income  taxes,  distribution  of  dividends,  and 

retention  of  profits  by  corporations  of  varying  size  classes 

and  industries,  1937 85 

XXIV.  Federal  corporate  income  taxes,  distribution  of  dividends,  and 

retention  of  profits  by  corporations  in  91  industries,  1937-  Faces  86 
XXV.  Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments  as  percent  of  net  profit 

before  interest,  by  profit  rate  classes,  1934-37 Faces  88 

XXVI.  Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments  as  percent  of  net  profit 

before  interest,  by  profit  rate  classes  and  industries,  1937—  Faces  88 

XXVII.  Federal  undistributed  profits-tax  payments  as  percent  of  net 

profit  before  interest,  by  profit  rate  classes  and  industries, 

1937 Faces  89 

XXVIII.  Federal    corporate   income-tax    payments    as    percent    of    net 

profit  before  interest,  by  equit,y  ratio  classes,  1934-37 Faces  92 

XXIX.  Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments  as  percent  of  net  profit 

before  interest,  by  equity  ratio  classes  and  industries,  1937 93 

XXX.  Federal  undistributed  profits  tax  payments  as  percent  of  net 

profit  before  interest,  by  equitv  ratio  classes  and  industries, 

1937 '_ : 94 

XXXI.  Federal-State  pay-roll  taxes  as  percent  of  sales,  by  size  classes 

(based  on  sales)  and  industries,  1938 Faces  98 

XXXII.  Federal-State  pay-roll  tax  payments  as  percent  of  gross  margin, 

by  size  classes  (based  on  assets)  and  industries,  1937 99 

XXXIII.  Federal-State  pay-roll  tax  payments  as  percent  of  gross  margin, 

by  labor  cost  classes  and  industries,  1937 100 

XXXIV.  Federal-State  pay-roll  tax  payments  as  percent  of  gross  margin, 

by  profit  rate  classes  and  industries,  1937 Faces  101 

XXXV.  State  and  local  property  taxes  as  percent  of  sales  by  size  classes 

(based  on  sales)  and  by  industries,  1938 Faces  110 

XXXVI.  State  and  local  property-tax  payments   as  percent    of    gross 

margin,  by  profit  rate  classes  and  industries,  1937 Faces  110 

APPENDIX  A 

TABLES 

I.  Federal  wartime  taxation  of  corporate  profits  1917-21 125 

APPENDIX  B 

TABLES 

I.  Calculated  capital-stock  tax  on  corporations  of   varving  size, 

1933-37 1 128-29 

APPENDIX  D 

TABLES 

I.  Tax  experience  of  312  identical   manufacturing  corporations, 

1934-37 132-33 


SCHEDULE  OF  TABLES  AND  CHARTS  IX 

APPENDIX  E 

TABLES 

Page 

I.   Number  of  corporations  filing  income-tax  returns 134 

II.  Number  of  corporations  in  1937  tax  sample 141-142 

EXHIBITS 

1.  Dunn  &  Bradstreet  tax  questionnaire 143 

2.  Department  of  Commerce  tax  questionnaire _       144 

APPENDIX  F 

TABLES 

I.  United  States  tax  collections,  1860-1938 146 

II.  Changing  revenue  sources  of  Federal,  State,  and  local  Govern- 
ments, 1913-38 148 

III.  Corporate  gross  and  net  incomes  and  Federal  corporate  income 

taxes,  1909-37 149 

IV.  Federal  taxes  and  corporate  income  available  for  reinvestment  or 

distribution  to  individuals,  1916-37__ 149 

V.  Effect  of  1932  abolition  of  minimum  income  exemption  by  size 

classes  and  industries 150 

VI.  Statutory  deductions  as  percentages  of  corporate  receipts  by 

size  classes,  1937 150 

VII.  Statutory  deductions  as  percentages  of  total  receipts,  by  size  of 

corporations  and  industries,  1936 151 

VIII.  Deductions  for  prior  vears'  loss  as  percent  of  taxable  net  income, 

by  industries,  1926-32 158 

IX.  Deductions  for  prior  years'  loss  as  percent  of  taxable  net  income, 

1931-32,  by  size  classes  and  industries 158 

X.  Consolidated   returns   in   Federal   corporate   income   taxation; 
number  of  returns,  gross  income,  net  income,  and  Federal  tax, 

by  industries,  1928-36 159 

XL  Comparison  of  corporations  filing  consolidated  and  unconsol- 
idated returns  in  1933  and  1934  by  industries 161 

XII.  Industrial  trends  in  the  operation  of  the  Federal  taxes  on  corpo- 
rate income,  1926-36 163 

XIII.  Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments  as  percent  of  profits  of 

corporations  of  varying  size,  1931-37 165 

XIV.  Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments  and  credits  for  invest- 

ment income,  by  size  classes  and  industries,  1936-37 174 

XV.  Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments  and  credits  for  invest- 
ment income,  by  minor  industries,  1937 178 

XVI.  Federal  taxes  and  corporate  income  paid  out  as  cash  dividends  or 
available    for    reinvestment    or    industrial    replaceijient    by 
small,  medium-sized,  large,  and  giant  corporations,  1931-37.  _       181 
XVII.  Normal  and  excess-profits  taxes  as  percent  of  net  before  interest, 

bjT'  profit  rate  and  equity  ratio  classes,  1934-37 183 

XVIII.  Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments  as  percent  of  net  before 
interest,  by  profit  rate  and  equitv  ratio  classes  and  industries, 

1937 : 186 

XIX.  Tax  payments  of  manufacturers,  retailers,  and  wholesalers  as 

percentages  of  sales,  by  industries  and  size  of  firms,  1938 188 

XX.  Federal-State  pay-roll  as  percent  of  gross  margin,  by  size  classes 

(based  on  assets)  and  industries,  1937 201 

XXL  Federal-State  pay-roll  taxes  as  percent  of  gross  margin,  by  labor 

cost  classes  and  industries,  1937 201 

XXII.  Federal-State  pay-roll  and  property-tax  payments  as  percent  of 

gross  margin,  by  profit  rate  classes  and  industries,  1937 202 


LETTER  OF  TRANSMITTAL 

Hon.  Joseph  C.  O'Mahoney, 

Chairman,  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee, 

Washington,  D.  C. 

My  Dear  Senator:  The  power  to  tax  is  the  power  to  define  the 
character  of  our  economic  system.  The  present  level  of  the  fiscal 
requirements  of  the  Government  increases  the  significance  of  the 
tax  structure  as  a  positive  factor  in  its  impact  upon  business.  Never- 
theless, the  present  tax  system  is  a  patchwork  put  together  over  the 
years,  a  residue  of  varying  philosophies  and  shifting  attitudes  toward 
different  business  practices.  This  becomes  even  more  striking  wheii 
Federal,  State,  and  local  methods  of  taxation  are  all  reviewed  m  their 
state  of  unco  ordination. 

Whether  so  planned  or  not,  taxes  inevitably  have  a  relationship  to 
the  problem  of  the  concentration  of  industry.  They  may  favor 
enterprises  of  differing  sizes.  They  may  encourage  or  discourage 
growth.  They  may  help  or  hamper  such  devices  as  the  holding 
company.  They  may  influence  the  character  of  capital  structures. 
They  may  penalize  enterprises  in  fluctuating  industries.  Such  inten- 
tions may  not  have  been  dominant  in  the  minds  of  legislators;  in 
fact,  the  results  may  have  been  quite  in  the  form  of  a  byproduct  of 
some  other  purpose.  Nevertheless,  they  may  be  important.  It  is 
the  purpose  of  this  study  to  examine  the  record  on  these  points. 

It  is  exceedingly  difficult  to  analyze  taxes  on  an  inductive  basis. 
The  frequency  of  changes  in  tax  laws  and  the  continual  fluctuation  in 
business  conditions  complicate  the  problem.  Although  this  report 
includes  much  new  material,  and  new  analyses  of  data  previously 
available,  there  still  remain  many  dark  spots  in  the  picture.  But, 
at  least,  the  problems  are  raised,  and  the  report  clearly  demonstrates 
the  importance  of  particular  tax  provisions  to  business  hfe  and  prac- 
tice. The  converse  of  this  approach,  taxes  as  sources  of  revenue^ 
has  been  regarded  as  outside  the  scope  of  this  study. 

Many  individuals  have  contributed  advice  and  counsel  in  this 
undertaking.  Although  they  are  in  no  way  responsible  for  the 
analysis,  we  wish  particularly  to  record  our  indebtedness  to  the 
Department  of  the  Treasury,  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission, 
and  Dun  &  Bradstreet,  Inc. 

WiLLARD  L.  Thorp. 

September  16,  1940. 

XI 


CHAPTER  I 

TAXATION  OF  CORPORATE  ENTERPRISE— THE  PROBLEMS 

OF  INQUIRY 

AUTHORIZATION    OP    THE    STUDY 

On  April  29,  1938,  President  Franklin  D.  Roosevelt  recommended 
to  Congress  that  it  provide  for — 

A  thorough  study  of  the  concentration  of  economic  power  in  American  industry 
and  the  effect  of  that  concentration  upon  the  dechne  of  competition.  There  should 
be  an  examination  of  the  existing  price  system  and  the  price  policies  of  industry 
to  determine  their  effect  upon  the  general  level  of  trade,  upon  emploj'-ment,  upon 
long-term  profits,  and  upon  consumption.  The  study  should  not  be  confined  to 
tiie  traditional  antitrust  field.  The  effects  of  tax,  patent,  and  other  Government 
policies  cannot  be  ignored. 

After  specif^dng  various  items  for  study,  including  improvement  of 
antitrust  procedure,  mergers,  and  interlocking  relationships,  financial 
controls,  trade  associations,  and  patent  laws,  the  President  referred  to 
''tax  correctives,"  as  follows: 

Tax  policies  should  be  devised  to  give  affirmative  encouragement  to  competitive 
enterprise. 

Attention  might  be  directed  to  increasing  the  intercorporate  dividend  tax  to 
discourage  holding  companies  and  to  further  graduating  the  corporation  incom^e 
tax  according  to  size.  The  graduated  tax  need  not  be  so  high  as  to  make  bigness 
impracticable,  but  might  be  high  enough  to  make  business  demonstrate  its  alleged 
superior  efficiency. 

We  have  heard  much  about  the  undistributed  profits  tax.  AVhen  it  was  enacted 
2  years  ago,  its  objective  was  known  to  be  closely  related  to  the  problem  of  concen- 
trated economic  power  and  a  free  capital  market. 

Its  purpose  was  not  only  to  prevent  individuals  whose  incom^es  were  taxable  in 
the  higher  surtax  brackets  from  escaping  personal  income  taxes  by  letting  their 
profits  be  accumulated  as  corporate  surplus.  Its  purpose  was  also  to  encourage 
the  distribution  of  corporate  profits  so  that  the  individual  recipients  could  freely 
determine  where  they  would  reinvest  in  a  free  capital  market. 

It  is  true  that  the  form  of  the  1936  tax  worked  a  hardship  on  many  of  the  smaller 
corporations.      Manj'  months  ago  I  recommended  that  these  inequities  be  removed. 

But  in  the  process  of  the  removal  of  inequities,  we  must  not  lose  sight  of  original 
objectives.  Obviously  the  Nation  must  have  some  deterrent  against  special 
privileges  enjoyed  by  an  exceedingly  small  group  of  individuals  under  the  form,  of 
the  laws  prior  to  1936,  whether  such  deterrent  take  the  form  of  an  undistributed- 
profits  tax  or  some  other  equally  or  m.ore  efficient  method.  And  obviously  an 
undistributed  profits  tax  has  a  real  value  in  working  against  a  further  concen- 
tration of  economic  power  and  in  favor  of  a  freer  capital  market. 

The  joint  resolution  establishing  the  Temporary  National  Economic 
Committee  provided  for  ''a  full  and  complete  study  and  investigation^^ 
of  ''the  effect  of  existing  tax  *  *  *  policies  upon  competition, 
price  levels,  unemployment,  profits,  and  consumption."  By  formal 
action  of  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  the  respon- 
sibility of  the  making  of  the  study  of  business  taxation  was  delegated 
to  the  Department  of  Commerce. 


2  CONCEN-TRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

SCOPE  OF  THE  STUDY 

''Taxation  of  corporate  enterprise"  is  a  phrase  of  confusing  g:en- 
erality.  Confusion  arises  out  of  the  many  different  kinds  of  corj^ora- 
tions  in  existence  and  out  of  the  many  different  types  of  taxes,  vary- 
ing in  magnitude  and  economic  effects.  It  is  therefore  necessary  to 
break  the  generahty  down  into  its  significant  parts  for  analysis.  At 
least  two  questions  are  posed  at  the  very  beginning:  What  corpora- 
tions?    ^Vhat  taxes? 

The  answer  to  the  first  question  is  one  that  must  repeatedly  be 
made,  since  the  instant  studies  are  undertaken  industry  by  industry 
and  also  by  size  of  corporation.  It  is  possible  at  this  point,  however, 
to  indicate  a  few  limitations.  ''Business,"  as  hereinafter  understood, 
primarily  refers  to  corporate  enterprise,  particularly  in  the  field  of 
manufacturing  and  trade, ^  except  in  chapters  IX  and  X  of  this  report, 
where  some  tax  data  are  presented  on  individual  proprietorships  and 
partnerships.  With  the  rapid  spread  of  the  corporate  form  into  most 
industries,  this  limitation  of  the  study  is  not  believed  to  be  very 
serious. 

Taxes,  taxes  everywhere.  The  only  properties  they  share  in  com- 
mon lie  in  the  circumstances  that  they  are  imposed  by  the  lawmaker 
.^nd  collected  by  the  tax  administrator.  Each  differs  from  every 
•other  in  the  magnitude  of  its  yield  to  the  Government  and  in  its 
economic  effect  upon  the  taxpayer.  These  differences  are  so  striking 
in  character  that  the  use  of  a  generic  term — "tax" — is  really  nothing 
more  than  a  dumping  ground  of  unrelated  charges  for  governmental 
services. 

One  form  of  tax  is  collected  from  the  owner  of  something  of  value — 
e.  g.,  a  factory  or  a  corporate  charter — a  tax  ho  must  pay  without 
regard  to  whether  his  factory  hums  with  industrial  activity  or  hes 
idle.  Such  a  tax  is  a  "fixed  cost"  of  the  business  that  runs  on  year 
after  year.  A  second  type  of  tax  may  be  based  upon  a  defined  unit 
of  production  or  sale — e.  g.,  a  package  of  cigarettes,  a  bottle  of  liquor, 
a  gallon  of  gasoline,  or  a  kilowatt-hour — or  upon  the  dollar  amount 
of  retail  sales  or  the  number  of  employees  retained  by  the  business. 
The  magnitude  of  such  a  tax  rests  directly  upon  the  volume  of  in- 
dustrial activity — in  a  word,  it  is  a  "variable  cost"  of  the  business 
enterprise.  A  third  type  of  tax  is  based  on  the  profits  of  the  business 
enterprise — that  is,  it  is  payable  only  in  the  event  that  the  operating 
equation  has  been  successfully  solved  and  net  income  results. 

The  effects  of  taxes  entering  into  the  fixed  or  variable  costs  of 
business  enterprise  do  not  leave  off  with  the  business  that  legally 
pays  the  tax  but  are  likely  to  extend  to  every  person  and  agency 
with  which  the  taxpayer  has  any  dealings,  either  directly  or  indirectly. 
In  the  classical  terminology  of  public  finance  such  taxes  are  said  to 
be  "shiftable"  in  character,  in  whole  or  in  part,  forward  or  backward. 
It  is  very  difficult,  if  not  well-nigh  impossible,  to  compute  with  pre- 
cision where  the  "incidence"  of  such  taxes  finally  comes  to  rest.  The 
difficulty  arises  not  only  out  of  the  varying  nature  of  the  "cost  taxes," 
viewed  a  priori,  but  also  out  of  the  complicated  characteristics  of  the 
taxpayer  and  the  tax  collector.  Who  is  he?  What  does  he  do?  Where 
and  when  does  he  do  whatever  he  is  doing?  And  for  what  purposes 
are  the  tax  moneys  spent? 

1  Data  on  so-called  "agricuUnral'"  corporations,  allhougli  available  in  the  source,  have  not  been  separately 
presented  because  they  are  believed  to  be  quite  unrepresentative  of  agriculture. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEB  3 

The  tax  on  profits  or  the  income  tax,  as  it  is  better  known,  cannot 
according  to  prevailing  opinion — and  no  empirical  studies  have  proved 
otherwise — generally  be  passed  downward  to  the  employees  of  the 
taxpayer  or  backward  to  his  supphers  of  raw  materials,  or  forward 
to  his  customers  or  the  ultimate  consumers  of  liis  products  and 
services.  The  income  tax  is  unlike  and  apart  from  all  other  business 
taxes  in  tliis  respect  (death  taxes  and  poll  taxes  excepted,  neither  of 
which  has  any  application  to  business  enterprise) . 

It  is  possible,  of  course,  to  improvise  hypothetical  cases  in  which 
the  income  tax  can,  in  principle,  be  shifted  over  a  long  period  of  time, 
provided  that  the  tax  is  either  highly  specific  in  character  (having 
application  only  to  certain  industries)  or  contains  substantial  exemp- 
tions. But  the  taxes  involved  m  the  present  inquiry  are  clearly  of  a 
general  character — in  short,  the  Federal  income  tax  applies  to  all 
corporate  enterprise  that  makes  a  profit,  with  proper  allowance  being 
made  for  certain  exemptions  (e.  g.,  agricultural  cooperatives,  etc.). 
Although  an  income  tax  may  over  an  extended  period  of  time  have  an 
effect  on  prices  (e.  g.,  by  curtailing  the  construction  of  new  facilities), 
it  would  be  true  only  in  a  period  marked  by  the  full  use  of  resources 
(i.  e.,  existing  plant  capacity,  etc.)  and  by  a  scarcity  of  capital  for  new 
investment.  Under  existing  circumstances,  however,  it  is  "noseplain" 
that  these  theoretical  possibilities  of  shifting  are  of  so  negligible  a 
jiature  as  to  be  disregarded  with  safety.^ 

The  study  has  been  divided  into  11  chapters,  7  of  which  are  ex- 
clusively concerned  with  Federal  corporate  income  taxation.  The 
size  and  industrial  problem  is  discussed  in  terms  of  statutory  rates 
and  exemptions  (ch.  II),  deductions  from  gross  income  (ch.  II), 
facilitation  of  intercorporate  affiliation  via  consolidated  tax  returns 
(cli.  Ill),  credits  for  intercorporate  dividends  (ch.  IV),  corporate  in- 
vestment in  governmental  securities  (ch.  IV),  the  excess-profits  tax 
(ch.  V),  and  the  surtax  on  undistributed  profits  (ch.  V).  The  aggre- 
gate effect  of  Federal  corporate  income  taxes  upon  corporate  funds 
available  for  dividends  and  reinvestment  by  various  types  of  corpora- 
tions is  examined  in  chapter  VI.  Next,  chapter  VII,  follows  a  study 
of  corporations  with  varying  rates  of  profits  (partially  reflecting  un- 
perfect  competition)  and  degrees  of  equity  financing  (ch.  VIII).  The 
remaining  chapters  deal  with  size  and  industrial  aspects  of  the  '^cost'^ 
taxes,  such  as  the  pay-roil  tax  (ch.  IX),  Federal  excises  (ch.  IX), 
sales  taxes  (ch.  IX),  the  property  tax  (ch.  X),  and  State  corporate 
privilege  taxes  (ch.  X).  The  concluding  chapter  simimarizes  the  find- 
ings of  the  inquiry. 

The  principal  sources  of  the  study  have  been  (a)  income-tax  data 
of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue  and  (6)  data  obtained  by  ques- 
tionnaires received  by  the  Department  of  Commerce  from  800  large 
manufacturing  and  mercantile  corporations  (for  1934-38)  and  by 
Dun  &  Bradstreet  from  27,000  small  and  medium-sized  business 
enterprises  in  manufacturing,  trade,  and  service  (for  1938).  See  the 
appendix  for  a  fuller  description  of  the  data. 

Such,  in  outline,  is  the  agenda  of  the  instant  inquiry  on  the  taxation 
of  business  enterprise.     The  nonagenda  of  the  study  needs  specifica- 

2  Theie  is  also  ihe  case  of  Government  price  regulation  of  business  "affected  with  a  public  interest" — e.  g. 
railroads  under  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission— where,  in  determ.ining  "reasonable"  rate  of  return 
on  investment,  income  taxes  are  actually  considered  as  a  charge  on  that  operating  income  which  the  ^us^ 
ness  is  deemed  worthy  of  earnina  under  the  Constitution.  Galvtaion  Electric  Co.  v.  Gaiie&lon,  258  U.  S. 
388  (1922^.  Also  see  C.  E.  Troxel,  "Shifting  of  Public  Utility  Taxes,"  Bulletin  of  the  National  Tax  Associ- 
ation, 25:  101-110  (1940). 


4  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

tion.  The  study  is  not  concerned  with  the  effect  of  taxes  upon 
natural  persons — their  consumption  and  investment  habits.^  Nor  is 
the  study  concerned  with  the  tax  advantages  and  disadvantages  of 
corporations  in  contrast  to  those  of  partnerships  and  proprietorships. 
In  the  latter  case  available  data  are  so  sparse  and  insubstantial  that 
it  was  not  believed  feasible  to  attempt  any  empirical  analysis. 

TAXES,    PUBLIC    RECEIPTS,    AND    GOVERNMENTAL    EXPENDITURES 

Nor  do  these  studies  purport  to  ascertain  whether  taxes  have  been 
or  are  excessive.  The  volume  of  total  tax  collections — of  the  Federal 
Government,  48  State  governments,  and  some  175,000  units  of  local 
government — has  been  steadily  rising  in  recent  times  (except  immedi- 
ately following  the  Great  War  and  during  the  depression  years 
1931-33).  This  increase  is  a  fact,  whether  tax  cohections  are  meas- 
ured in  total  dollars  or  in  per  capita  dollars,  or  adjusted  to  the 
changing  values  of  the  dollar.  The  per  capita  tax  jDayments  in  the 
United  States  amounted  in  the  aggregate  to  $23.42  m  1913,  $84.41 
in  1920,  $84.69  in  1930,  and  $114.09  in  1938.  The  Federal  taxes  per 
capita  amounted  to  $6.87  in  1913,  $53.77  in  1920,  $29.45  in  1930,  and 
$46.48  in  1938.^     (See  Table  I  in  appendix  F,  infra,  pp.  146-47.) 

But  governmental  functions  and  services — financed  in  major  part 
out  of  tax  collections — have  also  been  rapidly  increasing,  frequently 
at  a  more  rapid  rate  than  tax  collections.  The  excess  of  govern- 
mental expenditures  over  receipts  reflects,  in  a  not  inconsiderable 
part,  capital  outlays  for  physical  improvements  that  add  permanently 
to  the  wealth  of  the  Nation,  and  is  appropriately  financed  by  borrow- 
ing. In  other  cases  the  coincidence  of  declining  tax  revenues  and  the 
dire  need  of  governmental  aid,  especially  during  the  depression, 
results  in  substantial  budgetary  deficits  for  particular  years. 

To  speak  of  taxes  as  a  ''burden"  without  taking  into  account  the 
productive  use  to  which  government  puts  such  taxes — national 
defense,  police  and  fire  protection,  highways,  schools,  sanitation,  con- 
trol of  disease,  relief,  social  security,  to  name  only  a  few — is  obviously 
a  distortion  of  fact.  Taxes  are  not  collected  and  then  dumped  into 
the  ocean.  Like  the  sales  of  business,  taxes  are  operating  income  out 
of  which  the  Government  finances  its  manifold  activities. 

The  textbooks  frequently  contrast  taxes  and  prices  in  terms  of  the 
compulsion-volitional  elements  involved.  Yet  it  is  obvious  that  one 
can  refuse  to  pay  the  prices  of  necessities  only  at  the  expense  of  star- 
vation, death,  or  imprisonment — with  respect  to  many  things  there 
is  no  real  choice.  Likewise  a  person  can  refuse  to  pay  the  tobacco 
tax  by  not  smoking.  The  dift'erence  between  taxes  and  prices  cannot 
be  sharply  drawn,  and  in  fact  they  may  frequently  overlap,  espe- 
cially as  business  ceases  to  be  a  wholly  ''private"  function — as  if  it 
ever  were — and  becomes  affected  with  "public  interest"  and  as  gov- 
ernment assumes  functions  formerly  performed  by  private  individuals 
and,  institutions  (e.  g.,  education,  relief,  etc.). 

3  See  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  monocraph  No.  3,  Who  Pays  the  Taxes?  by  Gerhard 
Cohn  and  Helen  Tarasov.  1940. 

^  The  most  rapid  rise  of  sjovernmental  expenditures  occurred  during  the  first  Great  War  of  1914-18,  the 
economic  and  political  consequences  of  which  have  colored  povernmental  expenditures  ever  since^ — in  the 
form  of  vast  Army  and  Navy  expenditures,  pensions  and  soldiers'  bonuses,  debt  services,  aericultural 
relief  for  farmers  whose  lands  and  markets  were  disorganized,  etc.  For  a  study  of  the  efTect  of  the  Great 
War  upon  taxation,  see  Clarence  Heer,  "Taxation,"  Recent  Social  Trends,  pp.  1354-57. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  5 

The  clianging  tax  sources  of  the  Federal,  State,  and  local  govern- 
ments are  shown  in  chart  I.  In  1913,  the  earliest  year  for  which 
reliable  data  b}^  tax  sources  are  available  for  all  three  levels  of  gov- 
ernment in  the  United  States,  the  property  tax  (56.7  percent)  and 

Chart  I 

CHANGING  REVENUE  SOURCES  OF  FEDERAL,  STATE  &  LOCAL 
GOVERNMENTS,  !9I3  -  1938 


PERCENT    OF    TOTAL    REVENUE 
20  40  60 


80 


/9.'3 
/930 
/938 


/9/3 
/930 
/938 


PAYROLL  TAXES 

Hi 


CUSTOMS 


/9/3 
/930 
/938 


HIGHWAY  TAXES 


/9/3 

/930 

■  '  '"'I 

193/ 

S888?                  i 

f9/3 
I930 
1938 


PROPERTY  T^XES 


ALL  OTHER  REVENUE 


LEGEND 
^  f£D£ML 
V7\  STATE  S  LOOiL 


Source:  U.  S.  Treasury  Department's  Annual  Report  and  Bulletin,  Recent  Social  Trends. 
Department  of  Commerce. 

consumption  taxes,  including  customs  and  liquor  and  tobacco  taxes 
(30.5  percent),  furnished  the  principal  mainstay  of  the  public  reve- 
nues— in  fact,  they  contributed  87  percent  of  the  total  receipts  of  the 
Federal,   State,   and  local  governments.     The  relative  yield  of  the 


262698— 41— No.  9- 


g  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

property  tax  has  since  been  steadily  declining,  until  in  1938  it  fur- 
nished less  than  one-third  of  the  public  revenues,  in  contrast  to  the 
pre-war  era  when  it  furnished  more  than  one-half.  The  one-third 
produced  by  the  property  tax,  however,  is  nonetheless  more  revenue 
than  that  raised  by  any  other  tax  and  is,  of  course,  still  the  fiscal 
m.ainstay  of  most  local  governments.  Customs  has  likewise  been 
declining  in  relative  yield,  falling  from  13.7  percent  in  1913  to  2.3 
percent  in  1938. 

In  1930,  before  the  full  effects  of  the  depression  had  been  felt  by 
the  tax  system,  the  principal  public  receipts  came  from  the  property 
tax  (45.7'  percent),  income  taxes  (24.1  percent),  and  highway  taxes 
(7.6  percent).  These  three  taxes  in  the  aggregate  accounted  for  77.4 
percent  of  total  public  receipts.  Both  the  income  tax  and  the  high- 
way taxes  are  relatively  new  taxes  which  were  only  nominally  in  evi- 
dence in  1913.  The  income  tax  on  corporations  and  individuals  is  of 
primary  importance  to  the  Federal  Government — the  extensive  areal 
jurisdiction  of  which  makes  it  the  best  collector  of  taxes  related  to 
mobile  wealth  and  income — v/hile  the  highway  taxes  (motor  vehicles 
and  gasoline)  have  been  largely  collected  by  the  States. 

During  the  course  of  the  depression  and  the  consequent  atrophy  of 
income  taxes  as  producers  of  revenue  there  occurred  a  striking  resur- 
gence of  taxes  on  articles  of  mass  consumption.  The  States  widely 
enacted  taxes  on  retail  sales,  while  the  Federal  Government  renewed 
its  reliance  on  liquor  taxes  and  manufacturers'  excises.  The  tax  pat- 
tern was  again  changed.  As  in  1913,  consumption  taxes  contributed 
a  major  share  of  public  receipts — in  1936  they  accounted  for  more 
than  one-fifth  (21.7  percent)  of  total  public  receipts  and  more  than 
equaled  the  yield  of  the  income  taxes  (15.5  percent).  That  year  also 
saw  the  enactment  by  the  Federal  and  State  Governments  of  a  new 
tax  on  pay  rolls  as  a  part  of  the  social-security  program. 

In  1938  the  relative  importance  of  consumption  taxes  had  declined 
somewhat,  but  such  taxes  continued  to  account  for  a  major  share 
(18.6  percent)  of  total  public  receipts.  Taxes  on  income  (19.3  per- 
cent) and  wealth  (3.5  percent)  increased  relatively,  although  they 
still  lagged  considerably  behind  the  1930  figures.  The  pay^^oil  tax 
has  emerged  as  an  important  revenue  source  (9  percent)  to  both  the 
Federal  and  State  Governments. 

FEDERAL    TAXATION    OF    CORPORATE    PROFITS 

In  this  study  the  Federal  corporate  incom.e  tax  has  been  examined 
in  terms  of  its  effects  upon  the  corporation  paying  the  tax.  The 
industrial  unit  of  the  study  is  the  corporation  as  such,  artificial  creature 
of  the  law  though  it  be.  The  individual  stockholder  is  considered 
only  insofar  as  his  return  on  dividends  may  be  diminished  by  taxes 
on  corporate  profits.  This  Hmitation  of  the  study  involves  no  dis- 
tortion of  analysis,  except  possibly  in  the  case  of  the  surtax  on  undis- 
tributed profits,  where  the  full  story  cannot  be  told  without  taking 
into  account  individual  stockholders  whose  surtax  payments  varv 
with  the  magnitude  of  corporate  dividends  paid  out. 

The  corporation  is  theoretically  owned  by  the  stockholders  who,  as 
natural  persons,  ultimately  (though  paradoxicallv  not  necessarily  ever, 
at  least  in  practice)  reap  the  successes  and  suffer  the  failures  of  the 
corporation.     The   corporation,   it   is   said,   is   a   mere  les:al   conduit 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  7 

erected  for  the  benefit  of  the  stockholders.  But  these  general  state- 
ments are  hardly  applicable  to  all  types  of  corporations,  of  which 
there  is  a  confusing  variety.  The  small  corporations,  which  are  nu- 
merically very  large  (at  least  350,000  of  the  500,000  corporations 
annually  reporting  to  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue),  are  essentially 
like  partnerships  except  for  the  legal  form  of  organization. 

But  in  many  walks  of  American  life  it  is  the  large  corporation  which 
has  attained  a  state  of  dominance,  producing  the  lion's  share  of  the 
national  output,  its  plants  and  activities  located  throughout  the 
length  and  breadth  of  these  United  States,  and  its  stocks  trading  on 
the  national  and  international  exchanges.  It  is  of  this  latter  type 
that  it  can  be  said  that  the  corporation  is  ceasing  to  be  merely  an 
artificial  aggregate  of  individuals  and  is  emerging  as  a  very  real 
institution  of  vast  social  and  economic  importance  in  the  modern 
economy.  "The  usual  securit}^  holder  in  America,"  say  Berle  and 
Means,  with  particular  reference  to  the  investors  in  large  corporations, 
has  become  a  mere  "petitioner  for  the  wages  of  capital." 

The  larger  the  corporation  and  the  more  widely  distributed  the  stock,  the  more 
easily  can  an  existing  management  retain  its  position  through  control  of  the 
proxy  machinery.  Such  a  management  becomes  virtually  a  self-perpetuating 
body.  Such  control  without  appreciable  ownership  has  already  been  attained 
in  many  large  American  corporations,  such  as  American  Telephone  &  Telegraph 
Co.,  the  General  Electric  Co.,  the  Pennsylvania  Railroad,  and  the  United  States 
Steel  Corporation,  and  it  appears  to  be  the  form  toward  which  the  modern  cor- 
poration is  tending.  In  such  a  corporation  the  separation  of  ownership  and 
control  is  well-nigh  complete.  The  stockholders  no  longer  hold  the  position  of 
partners  in  an  enterprise;  they  have  joined  the  bondholders  as  suppliers  of  capital. 
They  are  merely  lenders  of  capital  with  a  return  which  is  not  fixed  but  contingent 
upon  the  will  of  those  in  control.  Their  right  to  vote  has  become  a  right  to 
revolution  rather  than  a  niethod  of  control.      -^     *     *  ^ 

These  statements  of  course  do  not  deny  the  fact  that  there  are 
stockholders  Avho  play  important  roles  in  the  management  and  control 
of  corporate  policies  and  activities.  Though  numerically  few,  there 
are  usualty  in  the  case  of  each  corporation  some  large  stockholders 
who  either  participate  directly  in  the  management  through  member- 
ship or  representation  on  the  board  of  directors  or  periodically  influence 
the  management  by  specific  suggestions  which  cannot  be  cavalierly 
ignored.^ 

The  corporation  frequently  commands  larger  resources,  employs 
more  persons,  and  exerts  greater  power  than  several  States  of  the 
Union,  even  assuming  at  times  the  attributes  of  sovereignty  itself. 

Walter  Rathenau  in  Von  kommenden  Dingen  *  *  *  suggested  that  cor- 
porate enterprises  had  reached  a  stage  where  they  were  almost  nameless,  soulless, 
and  without  any  individual  objective;  he  suggested  the  logical  possibility  that  a 
corporation  might  even  own  all  of  its  shares,  continuing  as  a  self-perpetuating 
organization  of  men  working  for  an  idea  as  abstract  as  the  concept  of  the  Nation.' 

The  corporate  income  tax's  central  dominance  in  the  Federal  fiscal 
system  will  grow  readily  evident  from  an  inspection  of  table  I.  In 
1940,  the  latest  fiscal  year  for  which  collection  figures  are  available, 
the  corporate  income  tax  accounted  for  approximately  one-fifth  of  all 
Federal  revenues.  In  actual  dollars  the  corporate  income  tax  in  1938 
gave  a  yield  of  $1,337,000,000 — a  more  m-ountaiiious  revenue  than 
has  been  raised  b}^  any  other  tax  or  in  any  yenT  save  during  the  war 
period  alone. 

5  "Corporation,"  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Scienr-es,  4:  419-421. 
'  See  "The  30,000  Mr.nagors,"  Fortune,  February  l&iO. 
"  Berle  and  ^Means,  op.  cit.,  pp.  419,  421. 


COXCENTRATIOX  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


-  S 


eCOIMCOr-iiOCO— <(N^ 


CO  aocc  c«3  CO  < 


>  00  «>  CO  CJ  I^  CO  -•*< 


I  "0  CO  •*  t^  !N 


OO  Ci  CO  <ii  TT  ' 

00.-i   ■-<  I 


co-*>o-Hr-^t^Oi 


I      ooOTt<'r>cococo 

■*!  -^  «  30  CO  -H 


>CO  CM 


^2 


o  a. 


goes 
ca  o  >i 

t-  c3.ti 

'^  •-:;  o  Q  Q  p4  <: 


O  00  (H      '  O  CD  iC  O  CO  CO 


(N-H  rt 


>i 

« 

CO 

c3 

£ 

TfOMtDC^OOOt^OiCD 


I  CO  lO  >C  ■*  ■«*'  (M        — < 
i  C^  .-H  Tf"  CO  OJ  Oi      I  »o 


-H^  C^, 


CO  o>  M<  O:'  a:  0-.  o  «       ^ 
TJ  CO  (N      ■  S^'  lO  Oi  »0       ■  ■<*> 


■^lo^ct^'-iocc^o 


CO(M 


c^i  ~  to  oi  — <     '  o   I  o 


.^  *^ 

ac 

o 

SK 

a> 

TJ 

gx: 

d 

fl 

hro 

a  a 

.2  a 

d 

x: 

t     I 


'  CO  00  00  kO 


o  fl  Q 


aa.^ 


O  c3 

8>. 


cs-cl 

M  a  H   •  a 


- 


££ 

^ 

C  t- 

X 

oi^ 

CD 

£:t;^ 

« 

§,^ 

3 
H 

a 
<5 

a  *^ 

o 

Slc/i 

5 

ogsi 

a 

0     ta 

g 

a^s 

s 

ri 

c  S-- 

1^s° 

i 

o|.a 

he's 

^v.^ 

r> 

g 

SI 

m 

B2 


COXCENTEATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  9 

The  relative  importance  of  the  Federal  corporate-income  tax,  how- 
ever, has  not  been  notably  on  the  increase.  For  though  in  1931  it 
accounted  roughly  for  one-third  of  the  total  Federal  revenues,  it  ac- 
counts at  the  present  time  barely  for  one-fifth.  The  explanation  for 
this  disparity  lies  in  (a)  the  high  sensitivity  of  income  taxes  to  the 
fluctuations  of  the  business  cj^^cle — in  the  depression  years  its  revenue 
yield  declined  disastrously,  and  only  recently  has  it  begun  to  approxi- 
mate the  position  it  previously  occupied — (6)  the  adoption  of  Federal 
taxes  on  liquor  following  the  repeal  of  the  eighteenth  amendment, 
(c)  the  expansion  of  manufacturers'  excises,  and  (d)  the  development 
of  new^  taxes  on  pay  rolls  as  a  part  of  the  social-security  program. 
In  spite  of  all  these  recent  changes  the  corporate-income  tax  remains 
one  of  the  principal  keystones  of  the  structure  of  Federal  revenues. 

Corporate  profits  have  been  continuously  subject  to  Federal  tax- 
ation since  1909,  when  the  tariff  act  imposed  a  1-percent  excise  tax 
on  corporate  incomes  in  excess  of  $5,000.  Prior  to  that  year  corpo- 
rate profits  had  been  wholly  free  of  Federal  taxation  except  during 
the  brief  Civil  War  interlude.^  The  ill-fated  Incom.e  Tax  Act  of  1894 
contained  provisions  applicable  to  corporations,  but  it  foundered — in 
a  constitutional  sense — as  a  direct  tax  levied  without  apportionnient 
as  w^ell  as  by  its  effort  to  tax  corporate  profits  derived  from  holdings 
in  State  and  local  obligations.® 

The  excise  tax  on  corporate  profits  w^as  essentially  a  compromise 
and  makeshift  measure.  The  Democrats  had  desired  a  progressive 
income  tax;  President  Taft,  on  constitutional  ground,  had  preferred 
an  inheritance  tax;  while  the  States  objected  to  Federal  trespassing 
upon  their  tax  reserves.  A  great  many  people  had  become  persuaded 
that,  because  of  the  unhappy  experience  with  the  1894  act  in  the 
Supreme  Court,  a  general  income  tax  was  impossible  without  a  con- 
stitutional amendment.  Pending  its  passage  it  was  widely  believed 
that  an  excise  tax  on  corporate  profits — a  tax  clearly  constitutional, 
since  the  right  of  Congress  to  tax  sugar-refining  corporations  ou  gross 
income  had  recently  been  upheld  ^^ — was  much  to  be  preferred  to  no 
tax  at  all.^^ 

In  transmitting  his  recommendation  for  an  excise  tax  of  2  percent 
(reduced  by  Congress  to  1  percent)  on  corporate  profits,  President 
Taft  called  attention  to  one  important  aspect  of  the  tax: 

Another  merit  of  this  tax  is  the  Federal  supervision  which  must  be  exercised 
in  order  to  make  the  law  effective  over  the  annual  accounts  and  business  transac- 


8  Income  taxes  collected  from  corporations  during;  and  following  the  Civil  War  (i.  e.,  1863-73)  were  rela 
tively  small  in  magnitude,  amountine  to  $68,000,000  out  of  the  total  of  $347,000,000,  or  less  than  one  fifth 
See  F.  C.  Howe,  Taxation  and  Taxes  in  the  United  States  under  the  Internal  Revenue  System,  1791-1895 
pp.  98-99. 

e  See  Pollock  v.  Farmers'  Loan  and  Trust  Co.,  157  U.  S.  429  (1895).  At  least  three  of  the  colonies  taxed 
income  (Massachusetts  starting  in  1634,  South  Carolina  starting  in  1701,  and  New  Hampshire  startmg  in 
1719)  and  Virginia  in  1786  tried  to  tax  income,  but  these  incomes  were  predominantly  those  of  natural  per- 
sons, as  was  naturally  to  be  expected  for  those  days  of  the  precorporate  era.  See  National  Industrial  Con- 
ference Board,  State  Income  Taxes  (1930),  I:  5.  19,  94,  and  100.  Also  see  the  Board's  study  of  State  and 
Local  Taxation  of  Business  Corporations  (1931),  ch.  I,  citing  temporary  taxes  on  corporate  income  in 
Pennsylvania  (1864).  Virginia  (1870),  and  Tennessee  (1871).  The  first  State  attempt  at  taxing  corporate 
profits  in  recent  times  came  in  1911  when  Wisconsin  adopted  an  income  tax  applicable  both  to  individuals 
and  corporations.  Also  see  the  extensive  survey  by  the  U.  S.  Bureau  of  Corporations  of  Systems  of  Tax- 
ing Manufacturing,  Mercantile.  Transportation,  and  Tran.-mis.-icn  Corporations  (1909-15). 

ic  SpreckeJs  Sugar  Refining  Co.  v.  McClcin,  192  U.  S.  397  (1904).  The  1909  act  was  upheld  as  a  "tax  upon 
the  particular  privilege  of  doing  business  in  a  corporate  capacity"  by  the  Supreme  Court  in  Fhnt  v.  Stone 
Tracy,  220  U.  S.  107  (1911),  at  p.  151.  even  as  applied  to  income  from  State  and  municipal  bonds.  uhere 
a  tax  is  lawfully  imposed  upon  the  exercise  of  privileges  within  the  taxing  power  of  the  State  or  Nation,  the 
measure  of  such  tax  may  be  the  income  from  the  propertv  of  the  corporation,  although  a  part  of  such  income 
is  derived  from  property  in  itself  nontaxable."  At  p.  163.  To  this  extent  the  Pollock  case.  op.  cit..  was 
modified.  The  Court  also  adverted  to  the  fact  that  "the  posses-ion  of  large  assets  is  a  business  advantage 
of  great  value:  it  may  eive  a  standing  which  shall  facilitate  purchases;  it  may  enable  the  corporation  to 
enlarge  the  field  of  its  activities  and  in  many  ways  give  it  business  standing  and  prestige;  it  may  give  credit 
which  will  result  in  mere  economical  business  methods."    At  p.  166. 

11  The  total  yield  of  the  1909  corporation  excise  tax  amounted  to  approximately  $129,000,000. 


10 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


tions  of  all  corporations.  While  the  faculty  of  assuming  a  corporate  form  has 
been  of  the  utmost  utility  in  the  business  world,  it  is.  also  true  that  substantially 
all  of  the  abuses  and  all  of  the  evils  which  have  aroused  the  public  to  the  necessity 
of  reform  were  made  possible  b}^  the  use  of  this  very  faculty.  If  now,  by  a  per- 
fectly legitimate  and  effective  system  of  taxation  we  are  incidentally  able  to  possess 
the  Government  and  the  stockholders  and  the  public  of  the  knowledge  of  the  real 
business  transactions  and  the  gains  and  profits  of  every  corporation  in  the  country, 
we  have  made  a  long  step  toward  that  supervisory  control  of  corporations  which 
may  prevent  a  further  abuse  of  power.  ^2 

As  passed  by  Congress,  the  Tariff  Act  of  1909  imposed  an  excise 
tax  of  1  percent  upon  ''the  entire  net  income  over  and  above  $5,000 
received  by  every  corporation,  joint  stock  company,  or  association, 
organized  for  profit  and  having  a  capital  stock  represented  by  shares" 
less  dividends  received  from  other  corporations  subject  to  the  tax. 
Following  the  adoption  of  the  sixteenth  amendment,  Congress  passed 
the  general  income-tax  law  of  1913  which,  in  addition  to  a  graduated 
tax  on  the  income  of  individuals  (ranging  from  1  to  6  percent),  imposed 
a  tax  of  1  percent  upon  ''the  entire  net  income  arising  or  occurring 
from  all  sources"  of  "every  corporation."  The  revenue  acts  of  1916, 
1917,  and  1918  successively  raised  the  rate  of  the  corporate  mcome 
tax  to  2,  4,  and  12  percent,  respectively.  Since  1917  the  corporate 
tax  rate  has  exceeded  the  normal  rate  for  individuals  and  the  differ- 
ence between  the  two  rates  has  in  fact  been  steadily  growing.  The 
1917  act  also  introduced  a  new  tax  on  corporations — the  famous  excess- 
profits  tax,  ranging  from  20  to  60  percent  of  the  corporate  profits  in 
excess  of  the  average  pre-war  return  on  invested  capital  (not  less  than 
7  percent  nor  more  than  9  percent).  The  operation  of  this  tax  and  its 
subsequent  modifications  by  the  1918  and  1921  acts,  as  w^ell  as  the 
special  war  profits  tax  of  1918,  is  described  in  appendix  A.  In 
1919  the  regular  income  tax  applicable  to  corporations  was  reduced 
from  12  to  10  percent.  Following  the  abolition  of  the  excess-profits 
tax  at  the  end  of  1921,  the  tax  rate  was  increased  from  10  to  12}^ 
percent,  at  which  point  it  remained  roughly  throughout  most  of  the 
roaring  twenties.  (See  table  II  for  details.)  In  1932  the  rate  was 
raised  higher  still  to  13%  percent  where  it  rested  until  the  close  of  1935. 


Table  II. — Federal  corporate  income  taxation,  1909-40;  amount  of  tax,  statutory  and 
effective  rates,  and  specific  credits 

[All  tax  figures  in  millions] 


Normal  tax 

Excess-profits  tax 

Amount 

of  tax 
reported 

Statutory 
rates 

Effective 
rates 

Specific 
credits 

Amount 

of  tax 
reported  1 

'tory*    h««<^^^^<^ 

Specific  credits 

1909 

21 
34 
29 
35 
43 
39 
67 
172 
504 

653 
744 
637 
366 
775 
937 
882 

Percent 

2 

2  2 

12 

10 

10 

10 

12.5 

12.6 

12.6 

0.6 
.9 
.8 
.8 
.9 
1.0 
1.1 
2.0 
4.7 

7.8 
7.9 
8.1 
8.5 
11.1 
11.3 
11.6 

$5, 000 
5,000 
5,000 
5,000 
None 
None 
None 
None 
None 

2,000 
2,000 
2,000 

*  2. 000 

*  2.  000 
<2,000 

*2,m 

Percent 

1910 

1911     .. 

1912_.. 

1913  .- 

1914 

1915 



1916 

1917.... 

1918..-. 
1919.... 
1920..-. 
1921.... 

1922 

1923.... 

1,6S9 

I  2,  606 

1,432 

989 

335 

8 

20-60 

30-65 
20-40 
20-40 
20-40 

1  15.3 

130.0 
1  15.2 
1  12.5 

1  7.7 
.1 

$3,000  +  7-9    per- 

cent.3 
$3,000+8  percent.3 

Do. 

Do. 

Do. 

1924 

...I..-- 

See  footnotes  at  end  of  table. 


"  Messages  and  Papers  of  the  Presidents,  17 :  7391. 


eONCENTRATIOX  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


11 


Table  II. 


-Federal  cor  pot-ate  income  taxation,  1909-4-0;  amount  of  tax,  statutory  and 
effective  rates,  and  specific  credits — Continued 


Normal  tax 

Excess-profits  tax 

Amount 

of  tax 
reported 

Statutory 
rates 

Effective 
rates 

Specific 
credits 

Amount 

of  tax 
reported 

Statu- 
tory 
rates 

Effective 

rates 

Specific  credits 

1925 

1,170 

1,230 

1,131 

1,184 

1.193 

712 

399 

286 

416 

688 

710 

1,025 

1,057 

(») 

(«) 

Percent 
«13 
«13.  5 
4  13.5 
12 
11 
12 
12 
8  13.  75 
6  13.  75 
«  13.  75 
6  13.  75 
"8-15 
«8-15 
161^-19 
16H-19 
14.  85-24 

12.2 
12.7 
12.6 
11.2 
10.2 
11.1 
10.6 
13.3 
13.9 
13.8 
13.8 
14.9 
14.6 

(«) 

(») 

(«) 

*■  $2, 000 

4  2,  000 

4  2,000 

3,000 

<3,000 

3,000 

3,000 

None 

None 

None 

None 

None 

None 

None 

None 

None 

Percent 

1926 

1927 

1928 

1929_.-. 





1930 

1931 

1932 

......... 

1933..-- 
1934..-- 
1935..-. 
1936-.. . 
1937.... 
1938.-.- 
1939 

1940.... 

7 

8 

25 

22 

43 

(8) 

(») 

(8) 

5 

0 

5 
6-12 
6-12 
6-12 
6-12 
f        6-12 
\      25-50 

.2 
.2 
.5 
.3 
.6 

}      (') 

12^  percent.? 

Do!' 
10-15  percent.7 

Do.? 

Do.? 

Do.? 
f  Do.? 
\$3,000." 

War-profits  tax 

Surtax  on  undistributed  profits 

Total  corporate 
income  taxes 

Individual 
income  tax 

Statu- 
tory 
rates 

Specific 
credits 

Amount 

of  tax 

reported 

Statu- 
tory 
rates 

Effec- 
tive 
rates 

Specific  credits 

Amount 

of  tax 

reported 

Effec- 
tive 
rates 

Statu- 
tory tax 
rates 

Effec- 
tive 
rates 

1909 

PercerU 

Percent 

21 
34 
29 
35 
43 
39 
57 
172 
2,142 

3,159 

2,175 

1,625 

702 

784 

937 

882 

1,170 

1,230 

1,131 

1,184 

1,193 

712 

399 

286 

423 

596 

725 

1,191 

1,276 

(«) 

(«) 

0.6 
.9 
.8 
.8 
.9 
1.0 
1.1 
2.0 
20.0 

37.8 

23.1 

20.6 

16.2 

11.3 

11.3 

11.6 

12.2 

12.7 

12.6 

11.2 

10.2 

11.1 

10.8 

13.3 

14.2 

13.9 

14.2 

16.8 

17.3 

(») 

(«) 

(8) 

Percent 

1910..- 

1911 

1912.-.. 

1913    .- 

1-6 

1-6 

1-6 

1-13 

1-63 

1-68 

l-GS 
1-68 
1-68 
1-50 
1-50 
1-40 
1-20 
1-20 
1.20 
1.20 
1-20 
1-20 
1-20 
1-55 
1-55 
4-59 
4-59 
4-75 
4-75 
4.75 
4.75 
4.75 

0.7 

1914..-. 

1.0 

1915 

1.5 

1916 

2.S 

1917 

5.1 

1918.... 

»80 

?$3, 666+io 
\    percent. 3 

j 

7.1 

1919.... 

J 

6.4 

1920    .. 

4.5 

1921.... 

3.8 

1922 

4.0 

1923—. 

2.7 

1924.... 

2.7 

1925    .. 

-- 

3.4 

1926-.-. 

3.3 

1927 

3.7 

1928..-. 

4.& 

1929.... 

4.0 

1930 

2.6 

1931—- 

- 

1.8 

1932 



2.8 

1933--- 

3.4 

1934-.. 

4.0 

1935  -- 

4.4 

1936.— 

145 
176 

(«) 
(») 

(8) 

7-27 

7-27 

2H 

1.6 
2.1 

Dividends  paid. 

do-- 

do.io 

6.3 

1937 

5.4 

1938.... 

6.1 

1939-.- 

(8) 

1940-.- 

r's) 

"■- 

I  Includes  the  war-profits  tax. 

*  Additional  tax  of  1  percent  on  dividends. 

»  The  percent  represents  the  rate  of  return  on  "invested  capital"  that  is  exempt  from  tax. 

4  Available  only  to  corporations  with  net  incomes  less  than  $25,000. 

5  Insurance  companies  taxed  on  12.5. 

«  Consolidated  companies  taxed  at  higher  rates  (14.5  percent  in  1932;  and  14.75  percent  in  1933;  and  15.75 
percent  in  1934-35). 

'  Of  capitalization  as  declared  in  the  corporation's  return  under  the  Federal  capital-stock  tax. 

8  Unavailable  (September  1940). 

'  Applicable  to  income  from  government  contracts  in  excess  of  $10,000;  the  amount  of  the  excess-profits 
tax  may  be  claimed  as  a  pro  rata  deduction  from  the  war-profits  tax. 

"  Inapplicable  to  corporations  with  net  incomes  under  $25,000. 

II  Plus  a  special  credit  equivalent  to  either  (a)  95  percent  of  the  average  earnings  in  prior  years  (1936-39) 
or  (6)  8  percent  on  invested  capital. 

Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years.  Note  that  these  figures  are  based  on 
unaudited  returns  (since  1916)  which  are  usually  for  calendar  years,  and  hence  may  not  agree  with  figures 
based  on  collection  reports  (usually  for  fiscal  years) . 


]^2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  Revenue  Act  of  1935  (applicable  to  1936)  introduced  a  slight 
graduation  into  the  corporate-income-tax  rate  structure  for  the  first 
time  in  the  history  of  the  Federal  revenue  acts,^^  ranging  from  12}^  to 
15  percent.  But  before  this  provision  of  the  1935  revenue  act  could 
be  made  effective  in  1936  a  new  revenue  act  was  enacted.  The  slight 
graduation  from  12)^  to  15  percent  was  increased  to  run  from  8  to  15 
percent,  and  a  new  surtax  at  severely  graduated  rates  (7  to  27  percent) 
was  imposed  on  that  portion  of  corporate  profits  which  were  not  dis- 
tributed to  stockliolders  in  the  form  of  dividends.  Tiiis  new  surtax 
had  been  origmally  designed  as  a  tax  to  supplant  instead  of  to  supple- 
ment the  existing  corporate  income  taxes.  In  1938  the  surtax  on  un- 
distributed profits  was  repealed  in  substance  (leaving  a  mere  remnant 
of  2K  percent),  and  the  graduated  rate  structure  of  the  normal  tax 
was  modified,  ranging  from  12}^  to  16  percent  for  corporations  with 
net  incomes  under  $25,000.  Corporations  with  net  incomes  in  excess 
of  $25,000  were  tentatively  taxed  at  the  rate  of  19  percent  with  a 
possible  credit  of  2K  percent  for  dividends  paid.^'^  The  remnant  of  the 
surtax  on  undistributed  profits  was  completely  repealed  by  the  1939 
Revenue  x\ct  (applicable  to  1940).  A  flat  tax  of  18  percent  was  im- 
posed on  corporations  with  incomes  over  $25,000.  As  under  the  1938 
act,  corporations  with  less  income  were  subject  to  a  graduated  rate 
structure  ranging  from  12^  to  16  percent. ^^  In  consequence  of  the 
two  revenue  acts  of  1940  the  normal  tax  on  the  smaller  corporations 
has  been  raised  to  14,85  percent  and  on  the  larger  corporations  to 
24  percent,  with  special  provisions  covering  the  border-line  cases. 
The  disparity  in  statutory  rates,  is  now  9.15  percent,  greater  than 
it  ever  has  been. 

The  trend  of  the  statutory  tax  rates  applicable  to  corporate  incomes 
has  been  steadily  upward,  except  for  a  plateau  period  during  the 
twenties.  Throughout  most  of  this  term  the  statutory  rate  was  flat, 
with  the  notable  exception  of  the  war  period.  Yet  it  would  not  alto- 
gether be  correct  to  conclude  that  small  corporations  were  taxed  at 
the  seif-same  rate  as  large  corporations.  A  special  factor  frequently 
came  into  play  in  the  form  of  a  specific  credit  varying  from  $2,000  to 
$5,000  against  net  income.  A  credit  of  that  description  was  avail- 
able to  all  corporations  for  the  years  1909-12  and  1918-20,  while  only 
corporations  with  incomes  under  $25,000  could  take  advantage  of  the 
credit  for  the  years  1921-31.  No  such  credit  was  available  to  any 
corporations  for  the  years  1913-17  and  1932  to  date.  The  slight 
graduation  of  the  rate  structure  since  1936  has  operated  in  an  equiva- 
lent manner  to  favor  small  corporations.^^ 

Passing  from  a  statement  of  tax  rates  found  in  statute  books  to  the 
dollar  and  cents  reported  by  the  Treasury,  these  trends  over  a  period 
of  time  may  be  graphically  underscored.     The  outstanding  fact  of 

13  Since  the  turn  of  the  century  there  have  been  proposals  in  Congress  for  progressive  taxation  of  corporate 
profits.  During  the  consideration  of  the  1924  Revenue  Act  the  Senate  made  a  substantial  attempt  to  impose 
a  steeply  graduated  rate  structure  on  corporate  incomes.  At  least  six  States  (Arizona,  Idaho,  Mississippi, 
North  Dakota.  Pouth  Dakota,  and  Wisconsin)  had  graduated  corporate  income  taxes  by  1935.  The  largest 
range  in  the  statutory  rates  occurs  in  the  South  Dakota  tax  ffrom  1 1-^  S  percent). 

14  The  rate  mechanics  of  the  1938  act  were  not  overly  clear  to  an  uninitiated  reader.  Instead  of  permitting 
the  deduction  of  85  percent  of  intercorporate  dividends  from  corporate  profits  in  determining  net  income  for 
normal-tnx  purposes  and  calculating  the  normal  tax  therefrom  separately,  as  under  the  193G  pct,  the  law- 
provided  that  a  tentative  tax  at  the  rate  of  19  percent  should  be  calculated  from  net  income  and  that  against 
such  tax  should  be  credited  (a)  16i/^  percent  of  the  credit  for  85  percent  of  dividends  received  and  (b)  2li 
percent  of  the  dividends  paid  out. 

15  The  specialized  treatment  of  banks,  insurance  companies,  China  Trade  Act  corporations,  and  domestic 
corporations  operating  in  United  States  possessions  was  abandoned  and  the  regular  provisions  of  the  1939 
act  were  made  applicable  to  the  same.  Mutual-investment  companies  continued  to  be  credited  with  divi- 
dends paid  out  rather  than  with  dividends  received. 

"  Infra,  pp.  26-27. 


wirnon8 


Jtwrtt^r^iH+mr 


OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  l^ 

chart  II  is  the  stupendous  soaring  of  the  income  taxes  during*  the  war 
period.  The  peak  was  of  course  furnished  by  the  special  excess-profits 
and  war-profits  taxes,  but  it  remains  noteworthy  that  the  regular  tax 
on  corporate  income  also  soared  and  substantially  remained  on  the 
high  level  of  productivity  set  by  the  war  period  (save  for  an  exceptional 
drop  in  1921  which  was  rapidly  recovered). 

In  spite  of  a  lowering  of  the  statutory  tax  rates  in  the  bountiful 
twenties  the  Treasury  continued  to  report  large  taxes.  With  the 
advent  of  the  depression  in  the  thirties  the  income  tax  dipped  sharply 
downward,  reaching  a  low  point  in  1932  which  was  only  slightly  above 
the  figures  for  1916.  The  recovery  in  income  taxes  has  been  almost 
as  sharp  as  the  preceding  decline,  and  in  1936-37  the  tax  returns  more 
than  equaled  even  the  peacetime  peak  set  in  1926.  A  not  unimportant 
portion  of  the  1936-37  figures  was  contributed  b}^  the  special  surtax 
on  the  undistributed  profits  of  corporations  (shaded  on  the  diagram). 

DEFINITION  OF  CORPORATE  PROFITS  FOR  TAX  PURPOSES 

The  Federal  Government  may  constitutionally  tax  corporations  on 
their  gross  incomes.  Deductions  from  gross  income  are  consequently 
matters  of  ''legislative  grace."  That  is,  the  Constitution  does  not 
require  them,  although  sensible  economic  policy  may  dictate  them  as 
inherent  to  the  concept  of  an  income  tax  as  contrasted  with  other 
taxes.  But  Congress,  as  Professor  Magill  pointed  out  in  his  study  of 
Taxable  Income,  has  displayed  "increasing  liberality  in  granting 
deductions,  except  in  the  case  of  losses  on  sales  of  capital  assets."  ^^ 

The  increasing  complexities  of  modern  taxation  of  individual  and 
business  enterprise  alike,  about  w^hich  there  is  much  complaint,  is 
indeed  an  inescapable  consequence  of  higher  tax  rates.  The  higher 
the  tax  rates  the  greater  the  necessity  for  defining  income  as  closely 
as  possible  to  ''economic  income"  in  order  to  avoid  inequities  and 
hardships  of  individual  taxpayers.  Moreover,  the  tax  administrators 
are  faced  with  magnified  problems  of  enforcement  of  the  tax  laws  in 
order  to  prevent  evasion.  The  interests  of  equity  and  revenue  needs 
coincide  in  requirmg  detailed  accounts  and  definitions  of  what  legiti- 
mately goes  in  and  out  of  gross  receipts  before  "taxable  income"  can 
be  determined. 

These  deductions  at  present  include  prixicipally  (1)  cost  of  ma- 
terials and  labor  (commonly  referred  to  in  statistical  sources  as 
"cost  of  goods  sold"  and  "cost  of  operation"),  (2)  compensation  of 
officers,  (3)  rent,  (4)  repairs,  (5)  bad  debts,  (6)  interest,  (7)  taxes, 
(8)  contributions  or  gifts,  (9)  losses  by  fire,  storm,  shipwreck,  or  other 
casualty,  or  theft,  (10)  depreciation,  (11)  depletion,  and  (12)  net  losses 
for  prior  years.  Interest  on  Government  obligations  is  included  only 
partially  m  gross  income  and  from  a  nontechnical  point  of  view  could 
be  regarded  as  a  deduction  to  this  extent.  Similarly,  85  percent  of 
the  intercorporate  dividends  are  taken  as  a  "credit"  from  gross  income 
and  in  this  respect  might  be  regarded  as  a  "deduction."  The  relative 
importance  of  these  various  deductions,  measured  as  percentages  of 
total  corporate  receipts,  is  shown  in  table  III  for  the  years  1917-37. 

17  P.  319. 


14 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEK 


<» 

rn 

« 

tf 

5^ 

< 

O 

J 

^ 

s 

O 

s 

2 

0 

8 

S 

o 

■>-» 

v 

rn 

5 

a 

o 

^ 

8 
a 

r. 

1-5 

'^ 

<! 

m 

1 

:?: 

g  «  •-     :t5 

■::a2=5t3 


Iz:^ 


oc*05^-^•^co^^^^05oio6o»-^«DMe>^eo•^»o«d^^ 


CC  CO  lO  ■ti  CO  c<» 


»O!O<NC<l(MWC0Tt<CJi-i.-H 


caj2  2.S  5  2  3  la  ©.tj 


!>^  a  _  e 


Hr  O  «)  3  o  ©.ti 


i3  3  PI 
o'O  o 


=3  53 


£2 


afl.2«-<s 


t^-*Tt<05COOcO':DtC'l^OCOt»->*<l^O'10MC^05M 

o  00  05 1>^  Tf  t>^  00  t^  oi  05  OS  o  '-<  o  CO  d'  CO  •<a<  ic  ec  b^ 


iC>5C^C^'^iC'CiOiO'CiC>CiO»C«0?0t^t^t-»t^ 


oousooosojevnoi^Ojicicooeoofi^occiN 
-H  rH  -i  rt  c^  c<i  c>i  -<  ■-<■  oi  M  (N  c^' 


coi^oeot^t^coicoot^cc-^osi^oo 
■•OJ  00  i-H  <-^  o  M  •^  00  '#■  c4  eo  lo  50  05  »' 


ioo«5eooocO'«*0'^e<ie^cDroo500»c<N»o(MO< 
iQO'-HC^'cSiC^cot^eocdcaoii-ioo'oioodoJ'ri 


C^Og-HCOl^ 


COCO^*TJ*COOOOOOO^ 


05  lO  rf 

OC^CO 


r-(e<iiooo«ocoT-(— iooa>t^«OT»<rHiooo-^OrtOr»< 

<*'  "*'  S  fc  si  2S  •^'  ^  «^  o  '^'  o  c^'  05  «  00  '^  «5  oi  -H  c^ 
^--iM(N(N(Ne^(NcoTt<^Tj<i*eocoMi-i,-Hr-cC^<N 


ot~"t^t^coc<)i-HC<i 


iotoiotC50»ocoe<ic<»eoeo'^o 


t^Tt<oiocoo5i-ie<i05eococooiOOt^>0'*'«*ieo«o 
T-J  c^i  N  M  c<i  c<i  CO  CO  c<i  CO  M  CO  eo  'i'  -^  eo'  co'  PS  CO  CO  CO* 


ooooosoNcococ^oosoo 


O  00  05  wo  »0  O  t^       05  O  e<«  IN  00  IM  i-H  r-i  c<i  o  o  t-' 

^'       ■       'rHrHrHrHrJjr^-T-^CviC^'lNNC^iCS'fNlNNCOCO 


c<iOfoooi-Hi-ieo-^cDO'*! 
im'  e<i  w  c^'  CO  CO  eo'  CO  CO  --j^  -*  • 


050>iCOi0'*<C0i-iO 
^  ^  ^  ^  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO 


I  lo  "o  lo  CO 


'  <N  O  Tt<  CO -^  50  «D  C1C0(N  t^rHOMCOt^OO 

i  N  c^'  M  ci  <N  ci  pi  STST^M  CO  CO  c<i  N  c^'  (N  M  ri  e^i 


ti«500«00000^-OS«0»OiOCO^INOO'^0'-Hrf<05'!*' 

ocdcou:^td-H■co'Ocdl^>co^^r-^■?dod-Hcocd>do6cd 

iO«OOt^iOi©t^t^OOOOOOOOOit»«OTf<»COt^OOO> 


t^tOO-^t^COOt^t^COOSCOIMcO^OMiOt^t^ 


t^OOOSO— liNeO'>*ilOCDt^OQ010'-'(MCOTt<»OOt^ 
.-H-H-H(NM<NcScS)(MC^JCac5'MCOCOCOCOCOCOOOCO 
0)0^0303CSO>OOSOSOSO^C^O>OC^OOOSC^OSO 


OONCENTEATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


15 


•»*<t--CSi00cD00t^O«CiM'^CCC>^>O(N' 


i«CO«O»O«Ct-'»<CC(MC>0'*-^>C»O 


1-1  CO  r-  ■*  t^  ■* 
CO  00  ^  CO  -^  »o 


t^  I>  (N  W  C4  Ci  c4  CC  CO  M  ■<^" 


t-,r^Tt<t^ooo»0'«*<'-<oo(Na5fot^Ttit>.co(Mu:5(MC^ 


C^M(N(NTt<-*T»<-<*<Tt<C0C0C0-<*<«Ct^l:^«0«0O<»»0 


cofooo5'«*<coo5esTt<eofoeccDcoo5 
t-:t-:coi^'t>:o6odoTfco-!(H>ctdi>«o 


Tftictcooocooooot^t^i^-^coooiro'Ct-coooTt' 

»-H,?d  O  CO  O  W  (N  "-^  'i'  00  00  to  to  00  ^  »C  03  t^  cd  >0  U3 


t^«oi-ioeoc>».-ii-( 


T»<Tj<coecc»5e«sNeoeoe<5Meo-<*< 


OoO'-i-<ooo>«ot>-i-icoeocoTj<oit^iO(NcoO'CfO 
c<i  (N  c<i  M  e^'  M  (N  (N  c<i  esi  e^  c4  es  c^"  CO  Tji  T»<  CO  e<i  c4  es' 


OOOt^^OiQC^lOOt^KS 


(N  O  Ci  O  «0  »0  ■>* -*        CO -*■<*•  ^  t^  «-!<£>  »0  ^  CO  C<  <0 

r-;  I-'       ■  fH  ,-H  t-I  -H  ,H  '-M-;  r-J  ^'  —i  l-i  N  C^  OJ  C»  N  N  ?» 


io«rc<»r»«-*ooo05t^eooO'^«oiMO(NTtioocoi-t 
es»  CO  c^'  cs  CO  CO  oi  <N  (N  (N  CO  CO  c^  CO  ■<i'  »c  •<*'  co'  IN  IN  Cii 


50  «0  O  <-l  "5  ■<*<  IN  O*  r-(  r-<  CO  »C  to  ■<*<  ^  O  O  O 

i-t  c<i  e^  e^'  c^'  IN  esi  c<i  fr^fr~C^«^  c^'  ^  ^  <^  «^  i^  «^  '^  s^" 


COC<505C5C0003'>*i-^00«00>"500tJ<I^OC^OOOOO 

06lOC0C0'(N-^'-HC0C0t^t^«dcD»O->3<OC0lOlrft^t^ 
iOCDcOOOOOCOCD*CiO»0>0»0»0*OCOi:OOCOcO 


ooooooooooooooooooooo 


t^OOO»0'-l<NCOTHU-5COt^OC050-^(NCO'*<>COt^ 
-Hi-H— i'NC-4(N(NC^<NC<«IN<N'NCOCOCOCOCOCOCOCO 
O  O  O  O  O^  O^  O  Q^  O  C^  O)  O  O  O  C^  0>  O^  O^  O  0>  03 


5^  ><"r 


CoO 

52  = 


-sill 

«.    o     Or- 

o 


a  > 


II  s 

<B  o  .  a 

o:  ^;: 

tc  s  >  S 
c/1  3  2  -: 


IQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  most  important  deductions — and  increasingly  so  in  recent 
years — are  naturally  those  for  cost  of  goods  sold  and  cost  of  operations 
which  have  constituted  approximately  two-thirds  of  total  corporate 
receipts.  The  most  important  single  deduction  remaining — aside 
from  the  miscellaneous  group — was  that  of  taxes  paid  in  1937;  in  1936 
it  was  that  of  depreciation;  and  in  1935  and  prior  years  (as  far  back 
as  1917)  it  was  that  of  interest.  The  tax  deduction  has  been  increas- 
ing, rising  from  a  low  of  0.9  percent  in  1919  to  a  high  of  2.6  percent  in 
1932  and  1937.  The  deduction  of  interest  has  been  steadily  declining 
since  1932  from  a  high  of  5  percent  in  that  year  to  2.1  percent  in  1937, 
lov/er  than  it  has  been  in  any  previous  year  for  which  data  are  avail- 
able. The  deduction  for  depreciation  has  likewise  been  declining 
since  1932,  although  not  so  rapidly  as  that  for  interest,  falling  from  a 
high  of  4.5  percent  in  1932  to  2.3  percent  in  1937  (which  is  equivalent 
to  the  period  1926-29),  nor  has  the  depreciation  deduction  reached 
the  low  point  of  the  pre-war  and  the  immediate  post-war  years  (1917- 
20)  when  depletion  and  wartime  amortization  were  reported 
together  with  depreciation. 

Next  in  importance  has  been  the  deduction  for  compensation  of 
officers,  which  also  has  been  declining  in  recent  years,  falling  from  a 
high  of  2.6  percent  in  1932  to  2  percent  in  1935-37,  which  is  lower 
than  for  any  other  year  except  1916.  The  deduction  for  rent  paid 
has  been  steadily  declining  during  the  short  period  for  which  data  are 
available,  decreasing  from  1.7  percent  in  1933  to  1.1  percent  in  1937. 
The  deduction  for  bad  debts  is  substantially  at  the  same  percentage 
in  1937  as  it  was  in  the  late  twenties,  one-half  of  1  percent  or  slightly 
more — it  reached  a  high  of  1.6  percent  in  1932.  The  drastic  drop 
in  the  relative  importance  of  capital  losses  reflects  the  limited  deducti- 
bility (not  exceeding  $2,000)  for  this  item  that  was  introduced  by  the 
Revenue  Act  of  1934,  falling  from  2.1  percent  in  1932  to  0.3  percent 
in  1934  and  to  0.1  percent  in  1937.  The  Revenue  Act  of  1938  (sec.  212) 
has  relaxed  the  limitations  upon  the  capital  losses  deduction.  The 
only  deduction  showing  substantially  no  change  in  the  period  for  which 
data  are  available  (i.  e.,  since  1925)  is  depletion,  which  has  amounted 
to  approximately  one-third  of  1  percent  of  the  total  receipts  of  all 
corporations.  It  is  a  deduction  of  very  major  significance  to  extrac- 
tive industries  and  of  no  import  to  the  vast  number  of  corporations. 

The  credits  (in  the  nature  of  a  deduction)  for  specific  sources,  of 
investment  income — e.  g.,  intercorporate  dividends  and  interest 
received  on  governmental  obligations — have  been  steadily  growing  in 
importance,  reaching  a  peak  in  1935,  when  they  amounted  to  3.2  per- 
cent of  corporate  receipts.  The  relative  decline  of  the  credit  for 
intercorporate  dividends  since  1935  reflects  presumably  the  changes 
in  the  revenue  acts  of  1936  and  subsequent  years  under  Vvhich  15 
percent  of  intercorporate  dividends  must  be  included  in  taxable 
income. 

The  excess  of  receipts  over  the  foregoing  deductions  and  credits 
results  in  net  income  for  tax  purposes.  Tak>'ng  net  income  (excluding 
deficits)  as  percentages  of  total  corporate  receipts,  it  is  apparent  that 
net  income  was  largest  during  the  war  years  (1917-19)  and  during 
the  prosperous  twenties,  when  it  varied  from  6  to  12  percent  of  total 
receipts.  Both  the  absolute  and  relative  amount  of  net  income  de- 
clined catastrophically  during  the  depression,  amounting  to  2.7 
percent  of  total  receipts  in  1932.     "While  the  figure  has  been  steadily 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  I'J 

rising  from  the  low  in  1932  to  5.2  percent  in  1937,  net  income  still 
remains  considerably  lower  than  the  high  points  reached  during  the 
roaring  twenties. ^^ 

The  relative  decline  since  1932  in  substantially  all  deductions— 
except  cost  of  goods  sold — has  naturally  reflected  itself  in  a  relative 
rise  of  the  amount  of  taxable  net  income,  increasing  from  2.7  percent 
of  total  corporate  receipts  in  1932  to  5.2  percent  in  1937.  But  the 
latest  figure  (1937)  is  still  relatively  lower  than  those  for  years  prior 
to  1930,  with  the  single  exception  of  1921  (a  depression  year). 

MAGNITUDE     OF     FEDERAL     TAXES     AND     CORPORATE     PROFITS,     1916-37 

Any  examination  of  the  effects  of  Federal  corporate  income  taxes 
upon  corporate  profits  obviously  depends  upon  the  coincidence  of  two 
factors — taxes  and  profits.  Corporations  without  net  income  clearly 
have  no  profits  and  likewise  pay  no  income  taxes.  They  have,  there- 
fore, been  excluded  from  the  study  of  the  relationship  of  income 
taxes  to  corporate  profits,  although  they  have  been  considered  in  the 
studies  of  statutory  deductions  from  gross  income,  without  which 
deficits  could  not  be  legally  established. 

To  deduct  the  deficits  or  losses  of  one  group  of  corporations  from  the 
profits  of  another  group  of  corporations  is  to  assume  that  the  corporate 
universe  is  a  closed  system  in  which  the  operating  profits  of  one  group 
of  corporations — profits  which  may  be  used  for  industrial  expansion — 
may  be  diminished,  canceled,  or  converted  into  deficits  by  the  losses 
of  another  group  of  corporations.  This  assumption  is  hardly  realistic, 
for  the  successful  corporations  still  have  their  profits.  The  losses  of 
the  unsuccessful  group,  of  course,  fall  upon  the  equity  owners  and 
may,  of  course,  if  continued  over  a  long  time,  fall  upon  creditors, 
workers,  and  the  community  at  large  (e.  g.,  if  the  plant  is  closed). 

The  amount  of  Federal  income  taxes  paid  by  corporations  and  the 
amount  of  corporate  income  available  for  reinvestment  in  or  by  cor- 
porations and  for  distribution  to  individual  investors  is  shown  graph- 
ically in  chart  III  for  all  corporations  reporting  net  income  in  the  years 
1916  through  1937.  The  length  of  the  bar  for  any  given  year  shows, 
in  billions  of  dollars,  the  amount  of  (1)  Federal  income  taxes,  (2)  cor- 
porate profits  paid  out  as  cash  dividends  (unavailable  prior  to  1926), 
(3)  corporate  profits  after  taxes  and  dividends,  (4)  charges  for  depre- 
ciation and  depletion,  and  (5)  interest  payments. 

In  1937,  after  paying  $1,276,000,000  income  taxes  (including  the 
excess-profits  and  undistributed-profits  taxes)  to  the  Federal  Govern- 
ment, corporations  had  at  their  disposal  for  plant  replacement  and 
industrial  expansion  and  for  distribution  to  investors  (as  natural 
persons)  some  $10,700,000,000.  This  sum  consists  of  $6,100,000,000 
profits  after  all  charges,  $2,900,000,000  depreciation  and  depletion 
additions  to  reserves,  and  $1,700,000,000  interest  payments  to  bond- 
holders and  other  nonequity  investors. 

The  magnitude  of  Federal  taxes  in  1936-37  compares  fairly  closely 
with  the  amount  of  Federal  taxes  collected  from  corporations  during 
the  later  tv/enties,  when  corporate  profits  were  considerably  larger 
than  in  1936-37.  Taxes  on  corporate  profits  were  largest  during  the 
war  era,  reaching  a  peak  in  1918  of  $3,159,000,000,  when  the  volume  of 
profits  was  more  comparable  to  that  prevailing  in  the  later  thirties. 

1-  Betwetn  1918  and  1932  not  inccme  was  subject  to  2  additional  credits— one  for  net  operating  losses  in 
prior  years  and  the  other  for  a  specific  amount  of  net  income— $2,000  to  $3.000— available  to  corporations  with 
net  incomes  under  $25,000.    The  effect  of  these  provisions  are  examined,  infra,  pp.  23-25,  36-38. 


18 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  III 


FEDERAL    TAXES    AND    CORPORATE   INCOME    AVAILABLE    FOR    REINVESTMENT    OR 
DISTRIBUTION  TO  INDIVIDUALS,  1816-37  (NET-INCOME  CORPORATIONS  ONLY) 


a 


LEGEND 

Federal  Corporate  Income  Taxes  (Inc. 
Excess-Profits  Taxes  for  ISIY-ai  and 

1933-37    AND   UNDfSTRtBUTED    PROFITS 

Tax  FOR  193^37) 

CORPORATE  PROFITS  (EXCLUDING  INTER- 
!  CORPORATE  DIVIDENDS)  AHER  PAYMENT 
OF  FEDERAL  !NCO?«E  TAXES  &  DIVIDENDS 
DEPRECiATION  AND  OEPLfciTICN 
(INCLUDING  AMORTIZATION) 


S 


INTEREST  PAID 


CACH   DIVIDENDS  PAID  OUT  TO 
lNDIVIOU;i,S    (.UNAVAILABLE 
PRIOR   TO    |^2b) 


UNAVAILABLE 


SOURCE":         STATISTICS   0"    LMCOME    FOR   RESPECTIVE   YEARS 


DEPARTI.1ENT  OF  COfl'ERCE 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  IQ 

As  it  is  to  be  expected  of  an  income  tax,  the  volume  of  Federal 
corporation  income  taxes  varies  closely  with  the  volume  of  corporate 
profits.  Profits  (after  taxes)  fell  from  10.9  billion  dollars  in  1929  to  2 
billion  dollars  in  1932,  or  a  decline  of  89  percent.  In  the  same  period 
taxes  dechned  from  l^o  billions  to  400  millions,  or  a  fall  of  67  percent. 
Meanwhile  the  revenue  act  had  been  changed,  increasing  the  tax  rate 
from  11  to  13%  percent  and  eliminating  the  specific  credit  of  $3,000, 
available  to  corporations  with  small  incomes.  Between  1932  and  1937 
profits  (after  taxes)  rose  from  2  billions  to  6Ko  billions,  an  increase  of 
205  percent.  Taxes  increased  in  the  same  period  from  400  million  to 
l^io  billions,  or  an  increase  of  224  percent,  somewhat  greater  than  the 
increase  in  corporate  profits. 

To  sum  up:  During  the  depression  the  volume  of  corporate  profits 
dropped  more  rapidly  than  the  reported  yield  of  Federal  corporate 
income  taxes.  With  the  improvement  of  business  conditions,  Federal 
corporation  income  taxes  tended  to  increase  somewhat  faster  than  the 
surge  of  corporate  profits,  although  the  lag  between  taxes  and  profits 
was  much  narrower  during  the  later  period  than  during  the  depression 
drop. 


CHAPTER  II 

FEDERAL  TAXATION  OF  CORPORATE  INCOME:  STATUTORY 
RATES,  EXEMPTIONS,  AND  DEDUCTIONS 

Size  has  emerged  in  recent  years  as  one  of  the  cardinal  problems  of 
Federal  corporate  income  taxation.  Do  the  corporate  income  tax 
laws  favor  big  business  or  discriminate  against  it  or  do  they  play  the 
role  of  a  neutral?  Is  small  business  accorded  different  treatment 
from  big  business  under  the  revenue  acts?  Is  medium-sized  business 
shown  favor  or  discrimination?  In  what  measure  are  existing  size 
differences  in  the  operations  of  the  Federal  tax  on  corporate  profits 
the  reflections  of  statutory  language  and  legislative  policies  or  the 
somewhat  inadvertent  results  of  administering  tax  laAvs  in  a  com- 
plicated economical  world?  How  do  different  industries  fare  under 
the  tax  laws? 

Size  and  industry  differences  in  the  operation  of  Federal  corpora- 
tion income  taxes  may  arise  in  several  ways.  The  Federal  revenue 
acts  may — 

(1)  Exempt  from  corporate  taxation  (a)  specific  industries,  thus 
favormg  corporations  engaged  in  such  industries,  or  (6)  a  minimum 
amount  of  net  income,  favoring  corporations  with  small  incomes.^ 

(2)  Adapt  the  rate  structure  to  specific  types  of  corporations, 
taxing  at  higher  rates  corporations  in  specific  industries  or  with  rela- 
tively large  net  mcomes  or  earning  relatively  high  return  on  invest- 
ment. 

(3)  Authorize  deductions  from  gross  income  which  may  be  more 
important  to  corporations  of  certain  sizes  and  industries  than  to 
others. 

(4)  Define  the  accounting  period  by  allowing  or  prohibiting  the 
deduction  of  prior  years'  losses,  favoring  or  discriminating  against 
corporations  with  fluctuating  income. 

(5)  Authorize  credits  against  (or  deductions  from)  net  income  for 
intercorporate  dividends  and  interest  on  Government  obligations 
(generally  held  by  the  larger  corporations). 

(6)  Further  size  variations  may  result  from  the  interaction  of  a 
complex  system  of  different  types  of  Federal  taxes  applicable  to 
corporate  profits. 

INDUSTRIES  EXEMPT  FROM  FEDERAL  TAXATION  OF  CORPORATE  INCOME 

The  present  Federal  revenue  act  (as  of  January  1,  1940)  exempts 
the  following  types  of  corporations  from  income  taxation:  (1)  Labor 
organizations;  (2)  agricultural  or  horticultural  organizations  (includ- 
ing county  fairs);  (3)  mutual  savings  banks  without  capital  stock; 
(4)  fraternal  beneficiary  societies,  orders,  or  associations;  (5)  domestic 
building  and  loan  associations,  substantially  all  of  the  business  of 
which  consists  of  making  loans  to  members;    (6)  cooperative  banks 

21 

262698— 41— No.  9 3 


22 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


without  capital  stock  organized  and  operated  for  mutual  purposes 
(including  credit  unions);  (7)  cemetery  companies  owned  and  oper- 
ated exclusively  for  the  benefit  of  their  members;  (8)  corporations  or 
organizations  (including  community  chests,  fimds,  and  foundations) 
organized  and  operated  exclusively  for  religious,  charitable,  scientific, 
literary,  or  educational  purposes,  or  for  the  prevention  of  cruelty  to 
children  or  animals,  no  substantial  part  of  the  activities  of  which  is 
carrying  on  propaganda  or  otherwise  attempting  to  influence  legisla- 
tion; (9)  business  leagues,  chambers  of  commerce,  real-estate  boards, 
and  boards  of  trade;  (10)  civic  leagues  or  organizations  for  the  promo- 
tion of  social  welfare;  (11)  local  associations  of  employees;  (12)  social 
clubs  owned  and  operated  exclusively  for  pleasure  and  recreation;  (13) 
local  benevolent  life-insurance  associations;  ^  (14)  mutual  ditch  or 
irrigation  companies;  (15)  mutual  or  cooperative  telephone  com- 
panies; ^  (16)  farmers  or  other  mutual,  hail,  cyclone,  casualty,  or  fire- 
insurance  companies;^  (17)  cooperative  associations  engaged  in  mar- 
keting the  products  of  farmers,  fruit  growers,  livestock  growers,  dairy- 
men, etc.;*  (18)  cooperative  associations  engaged  in  purchasing  sup- 
plies and  equipment  for  farmers,  fruit  growers,  livestock  growers, 
dairymen,  etc.;^  (19)  corporations  organized  to  finance  crop  opera- 
tions and  operated  in  conjunction  with  marketing  or  purchasing  asso- 
ciations; (20)  corporations  organized  for  the  purpose  of  holding  title 
or  collecting  income  and  turning  same  over  to  a  tax-exempt  organiza- 
tion; (21)  corporations  chartered  by  Congress  and  exempted  from 
Federal  income  taxes  by  the  act  of  incorporation;  (22)  voluntary 
employees'  beneficiary  associations;  (23)  local  teachers'  retirement- 
fund  associations;  and  (24)  religious  or  apostohc  associations  or 
corporations.^ 

This  list  of  exem.pt  corporations  represents  the  cum.ulabive  results 
of  approxim.ately  three  decades  of  tax  legislation.  The  trend  of  this 
exem.ption  legislation  is  quite  clear — the  types  of  exemptions  have 
grown  3^ear  by  year  more  num.erous.  The  initial  1909  tax  exem.pted 
only  corporations  falling  in  types  1,  2,  4,  and  8.  Substantially  each 
following  revenue  act  has  enlarged  the  num.ber  of  exem.ptions  or 
broadened  existing  types.  Thus  the  1913  act  added  types  3,  5,  7,  9, 
and  10,  and  added  the  clause  ^'scientific"  to  type  8.  The  1916  act 
added  types  6,  12,  14,  15,  16,  17,  18,  and  21.  The  Revenue  Act  of 
1924  added  types  11  and  13.  The  Revenue  Act  of  1928  added  types 
22  and  23.     In  only  a  few  instances  have  efforts  at  specific  exem.ption 

1  At  least  85  percent  or  more  of  their  income  must  be  collected  from  members  for  the  sole  purpose  of 
meeting  losses  and  expenses. 

2  Ibid. 

3  This  provision,  coupled  with  the  special  deduction  allowed  by  sec.  207  (c)  (3)  of  the  Internal  Revenue 
Code,  has  been  so  broadly  construed  by  the  courts  and  tax  administrators  as  to  afford  complete  tax  exemp- 
tion to  all  mutual  insurance  companies  other  than  life.  See  Commissioner  v.  National  Grange  Mutual  Lia- 
bility Co.,  80  F.  (2<\)  316  (1935),  holding  exempt  from  Federal  tax  a  company  insuring  in  10  States  the  mem- 
bers of  the  National  Grange  against  liability  arising  from  the  use  of  automobiles. 

*  "An  association  which  has  capital  stock  will  not  for  such  reason  be  denied  exemption  (1)  if  the  dividend 
rate  of  such  stock  is  fixed  at  not  to  exceed  the  legal  rate  of  interest  in  the  State  of  incorporation  or  8  percent 
per  annum,  whichever  is  greater,  on  the  value  of  the  consideration  for  which  the  stock  was  issued,  and  (2) 
if  substantially  all  of  such  stock  *  *  *  is  owned  by  producers  who  market  their  products  or  purchase 
their  supplies  and  equipment  through  the  association."  Nor  is  the  exemption  precluded  by  "the  accu- 
mulation and  maintenance  of  a  reserve  required  by  State  statute,  or  the  accumulation  and  maintenance  of 
a  reasonable  reserve  or  surplus  for  any  necessary  purposes,  such  as  to  provide  for  the  erection  of  buildings 
and  facilities  required  in  business  or  for  the  purchase  and  installment  of  machinery  and  equipment  or  to 
require  indebtedness  incurred  for  such  purpose."    Regulations  103,  art.  101  (12)-1. 

«  The  foregoing  footnote  also  applies  to  this  exemption.  It  should  be  observed  that  "cooperative  organ- 
izations engaged  in  occupations  dissimilar  from  those  of  farmers,  fruit  growers,  and  the  like,  such  as  mar- 
keting building  materials,  are  not  exempt."    Op.  cit. 

6  Internal  Revenue  Laws  (1939),  sec.  101.  Also  see  generally  art.  103  of  Regulations  101.  The  above  list 
may  superficially  appear  numerically  more  extensive  than  the  exemptions  listed  in  the  code,  since  each 
type  of  exemption  was  listed  separately,  although  a  single  code  paragraph  may  cover  several  types. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER  23 

been  defeated,  as  an  attempt  in  1921  to  exempt  corporations  organized 
to  promote  cooperative  hom.e  ownership/  an  attempt  in  1926  to 
exempt  mutual  dairy  loan  associations,^  and  an  attempt  in  1936  to 
exempt  water-users'  associations  operating  Federal  reclamation  proj- 
ects.® 

The  surtax  on  undistributed  profits  imposed  by  the  Revenue  Act 
of  1936  specifically  exem.pted  from  its  provisions  banks,  insurance 
com,panies,  joint-stock  land  banks,  China  Trade  Act  corporations^ 
corporations  in  banki'uptcy  or  receivership,  foreign  corporations,  and 
corporations  operating  in  the  Territorial  possessions  of  the  United 
States. 

Obviously  not  all  of  these  exem.ptions  are  of  equal  importance. 
Sonae  exemptions  are  found  in  substantially  every  tax  law,  for  exam.ple, 
the  exem^ption  in  favor  of  religious,  charitable,  scientific,  literary,  and 
educational  institutions.  Other  exemptions  reflect  the  strong  pressure 
of  special  interests.  The  m.ajor  exem.ptions  are  probably  the  agri- 
cultural m.arketing  and  purchasing  ' 'cooperatives"  and  m.utual  insur- 
ance com^panies  other  than  life. 

STATUTORY    EXEMPTION    OF    MINIMUM    NET    INCOME 

The  original  Corporation  Excise  Act  of  1909  applied  only  to  cor- 
porate net  incom.es  above  $5,000.  This  exemption  of  the  initial 
$5,000  of  net  income  rem.ained  in  eftect  during  the  life  of  the  excise  tax, 
expiring  in  March  1913,  when  the  first  income  tax  under  the  sixteenth 
amendm.ent  was  adopted.  The  1913  Revenue  Act  contained  no 
proA'ision  exempting  a  m.inim.um,  amount  of  corporate  net  income, 
although  such  an  exemption  was  allowed  in  the  case  of  natural  persons. 
The  excess-profits  tax  of  1917  reintroduced  the  concept  of  a  mjnimum 
amount  of  corporate  net  incom.e  free  from  Federal  taxation  by  ex- 
em.pting  the  first  $3,000  of  corporate  profits  from  its  provisions.  The 
1918  Revenue  Act  contained  an  exemption  of  the  initial  $2,000 
corporate  net  incom.e  from  the  ordinary  income  tax.  In  1921  this 
exemption  of  $2,000  was  restricted  to  corporations  having  net  incom.es 
under  $25,000.  In  1928  the  amount  of  the  exem.ption  was  raised  to 
$3,000,  at  which  level  it  remained  through  the  taxable  year  1931. 
The  Revenue  Act  of  1932  repealed  this  provision  and  since  that  time 
all  corporate  profits  in  excess  of  statutory  deductions  and  credits  have 
been  subject  to  Federal  tax  without  any  fiat  exem.ption. 

At  the  tim.e  of  its  original  introduction  into  the  1909  act  the  ex- 
em.ption was  severely  ciiticized  by  Senator  Elihu  Root,  whose  view  in 
this  respect  was  essentially  reiterated  by  Secretary  of  the  Treasury 
Ogden  Mills  during  the  consideration  of  the  1932  Revenue  Act  by  the 
House  Ways  and  Means  Comm.ittee.^^  That  this  exem.ption  of  a  basic 
minim.um.  of  corporate  net  incom.e  was  designed  to  favor  small  enter- 
prise— insofar  as  identified  with  corporations  having  small  net  income — 
is  fairly  clear  from  legislative  record  and  from,  such  statistical  data 
as  are  at  hand  on  the  operation  of  the  exemption.  Obviously  the 
factor  of  adm.inistrative  convenience  (eliminating  the  num.erous  tax 
returns  of  corporations  with  small  income)  was  a  relevant  considera- 

7  See  Cong.  Rec,  61:  7184-7186. 
*  69th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  House  report,  p.  36. 
»  See  Cong.  Rec,  80:  9098. 

5"  "I  never  knew  of  any  justification  in  principle  for  that  exemption."    Hearings  on  Revenue  Revision 
1932,  p.  22.    The  remarks  of  Senator  Root  maj-  be  found  in  Cong.  Rec.  44: 4004. 


24  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

tion,  but  this  factor  certainly  did  not  account  for  the  exemption 
originally,  nor  is  it  believed  to  have  played  any  important  role  since 
1921,  when  the  exemption  was  limited  to  corporations  with  net 
incomes  under  $25,000. 

The  Blakeys  in  their  history  of  The  Federal  Income  Tax  cite  a 
contemporary  and  dire  warning  by  Senator  Hale  that — 

if  amendments  did  not  provide  for  exemption  [of  small  corporations],  representa- 
tives of  hundreds  of  small  corporations  would  swoop  down  on  Washington  and  not 
only  make  things  miserable  for  Senators  and  Representatives  but  get  up  such  an 
agitation  against  the  corporation  tax  that  general  tariff  legislation  itself  would 
stand  in  danger  of  defeat. ^^ 

An  amendment  relieving  all  corporations  with  net  incomes  under 
$5,000  (the  specific  amount  of  the  exemption)  from  submitting  detailed 
tax  returns  to  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue,  upon  the  filing  of 
an  informal  affidavit  stating  that  net  income  was  less  than  $5,000, 
was  decisively  defeated. ^^ 

Statistical  data  on  the  operation  of  this  specific  exemption  are 
unfortunately  available  only  in  a  rather  indirect  manner  and  for  only  a 
single  year  (1931).  These  data  permit  computations  by  size  classes 
and  industries  of  the  effective  rate  of  the  Federal  corporation  income 
tax  (i.  e.,  tax  as  percentage  of  net  income  after  all  deductions,  including 
prior  years'  losses  and  credits  for  interest  on  Government  obligations 
and  intercorporate  dividends).  The  precise  number  of  corporations 
claiming  the  $3,000  exemption  can,  unfortunately,  not  be  laiown  by 
size  classes,  since  size  of  assets  and  size  of  net  income  are  not  invariably 
correlated.^"'  Since  the  statutory  income-tax  rate  on  corporations  in 
1931  was  flat,  lower  effective  tax  rates  for  certain  size  classes  indicate 
that  corporations  in  such  size  classes  made  substantial  use  of  the 
specific  credit  of  $3,000  and  the  difference  between  the  eft'ective  rate 
and  the  statutory  rate  of  12  percent  can  be  taken  to  show  the  quantita- 
tive significance  of  the  exemption  to  corporations  of  varying  size 
classes. 

From  these  data  it  is  apparent  that  the  specific  credit  for  $3,000 
operated  to  reduce  the  statutory  tax  rate  on  manufacturing  corpora- 
tions with  assets  under  $50,000  by  approximately  300  percent  (effec- 
tive rate  of  3.4  percent,  as  compared  with  the  statutory  rate  of  12 
percent).  See  chart  IV.  In  other  industries  the  role  of  the  exemp- 
tion was  even  greater,  as  in  trade,  construction  and  finance,  while  the 
exemption  was  of  slightly  less  importance  to  public  utilities  and 
service,  and  was  of  least  importance  in  mining  where  the  exemption 
operated  to  reduce  the  statutory  effective  rate  by  one-half.  Among 
the  manufacturing  industries  the  exemption  played  a  very  important 
role  in  depressing  the  statutory  tax  rate  on  the  smallest  corporations 
in  stone,  clay,  glass,  textiles,  forest  products,  printing,  and  metals. 
The  effect  of  the  exemption  was  largely  limited  to  corporations  with 
assets  under  $250,000  (except  in  finance  and  forest  products  where 
corporations  with  assets  from  $250,000  to  $500,000  were  visibly 
affected).  No  substantial  depressing  effect  can  be  noted  in  the  case 
of  corporations  with  assets  over  $1,000,000. 

The  1932  repeal  of  the  exemption  of  the  initial  $3,000  resulted  in 
very  substantial  increases  in  the  effective  tax  rates  on  small  corporate 

II  p.  46n. 

>2  Cong.  Rec,  44:  4235-4236. 

IS  For  a  frequency  distribution  of  corporation  income-tax  returns  classified  by  size  of  net  income  (or  deficit) 
and  total  assets  in  1936,  see  Statistics  of  Income  for  1936,  pt.  2,  pp.  42-43, 167-183. 


EFFECT  OF  1932  ABOLITION  OF  MINIMUM  INCOME 
EXEMPTION 

BY  SIZE  CLASSES  AND  MAJOR  INDUSTRIES 
1931  - 1932 

(NET- INCOME  CORPORATIONS  ONLY) 


TAX  AS  %  OF 
TAXABLE  NET 
INCOME      ,. 


ASSET   S/ZE   Cl./kSSE'S 


PtRCtNT    TOTAL   MANUFACTURING 


CONSTRUCTION 


PUBLIC  UTILITIES 


FOOD  a   BEVERAGES 


FOREST  PRODUCTS 


STONE.  CLAY  6  GLASS 


SOURCE:-  Computed  raoM  the  SouficeaooK  oa  Tua  St/it/stical   Section  op  the  Sune/tu  o/^  //VTEfiNAi  /?£i/£/iu£ 

2G2698— 41— No.  9     (Face  p.  24) 


m-nr^ 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  25 

enterprise,  in  many  cases  the  effect  being  very  drastic.  Any  com- 
parison of  the  effective  tax  rates  for  1931  and  1932  must  take  into 
account  the  change  in  the  statutory  rate  between  the  2  years,  which 
was  raised  from  12  percent  in  1931  to  13%  percent  in  1932,  an  increase 
in  1932  of  14}^  percent  over  the  1931  statutory  rate.  This  shght 
increase  in  the  statutory  rate  is  substantially  mirrored  in  the  1932 
increase  in  the  effective  tax  for  corporations  with  assets  over  $250,000. 
The  effective  tax  rates  of  the  small  corporations  (i.  e.,  with  assets 
under  $50,000),  however,  more  than  quintupled  between  1931  and 
1932,  in  the  case  of  manufacturing,  trade,  and  finance.  The  rate  on 
minmg  doubled,  while  the  rates  for  construction  and  public  utilities 
increased  more  than  fourfold.  In  other  words,  the  heaviest  increase 
in  Federal  corporate  income  taxation  during  the  course  of  the  de- 
pression fell  on  the  smallest  corporations. 

STATUTORY  RATE  STRUCTURES 

Throughout  the  larger  period  during  which  the  Federal  Government 
has  taxed  corporation  profits,  the  statutory  rate  structure  has  been 
flat  and  not  graduated,  in  contrast  to  the  rate  structure  of  the  indi- 
vidual income  tax  which  has  been  graduated  since  its  inception  under 
the  sixteenth  amendment.  There  have  been,  however,  proponents  of 
a  steeplj^-graduated  tax  in  corporation  profits  ever  since  1900  and 
possibly  before.  When  the  1909  act  was  passed  a  valiant  attempt 
was  made  to  graduate  the  rate  structure  on  corporate  tax  v/ithout 
success. ^^  The  war  excess-profits  tax  of  1917-21,  the  purpose  and 
effect  of  which  was  entirely  different  from  the  ordinary  corporate 
income  tax,^^  contained  a  steeply  graduated  rate  structure  consisting 
of  five  brackets  ranging  from  20  to  60  percent  of  the  income  in  excess 
of  the  presumed  norm.  The  Revenue  Act  of  1924  as  it  passed  the 
Senate  contained  a  steeply  graduated  rate  structure,  but  this  provision 
was  eliminated  by  the  House. 

The  imposition  of  a  slight  penalty  tax  in  1932  on  inter  affiliated 
corporations  filing  consolidated  income  tax  returns  may  perhaps  be 
cited  as  an  indirect  attempt  to  penalize  one  sort  of  bigness,  since  the 
corporations  making  use  of  the  consolidated  returns  device  tended  to 
fall  in  the  larger-size  classes.  But  this  discriminatory  tax,  wliich  was 
ver}^  slight  in  character  (three-fourths  of  1  percent  in  1932  and  1  per- 
cent in  1933),  was  designed  primarily  to  offset  the  undoubted  tax 
advantages  of  corporations  making  use  of  the  consolidated  returns 
device.  From  one  point  of  view,  the  whole  technique  of  permitting 
consolidated  returns,  with  or  without  a  penalty  tax,  may  rather  be 
cited  as  a  tax  device  for  favoring  large  and  complex  corporate  systems 
by  specially  adapting  tax  procedure  to  their  needs.  This  last  observa- 
tion, however,  is  a  controversial  point  and  need  not  be  insisted  upon 
in  this  connection, ^^  although  it  was  clearly  pointed  out  by  Mr. 
Robert  Jackson,  then  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue,  during  the 
congressional  hearing  on  the  1935  Revenue  Act.^^ 

"  Cf.  a  proposal  by  Senator  Hitchcock  for  "an  additional  graduated  income  tax  of  5  percent  on  all  corpora- 
tions having  $100,000,000  capital  or  more,  provided  they  control  25  percent  of  the  production  of  any  article 
in  the  United  States,"  and  a  tax  of  15  percent  where  the  control  exceeded  33J.ij  percent.  See  Cong.  Rec, 
50:  2020. 

"  See  appendix  A. 

^6  See  the  following  chapter. 

"  See  Hearings  on  the  Revenue  Act,  1935,  before  the  Senate  Finance  Committee,  74th  Cong.,  1st  sess., 
pp.  223-236. 


2G  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

It  was  however,  during  the  consideration  of  the  1935  Revenue  Act 
that  corporate  size  emerged  as  the  focal  problem  of  Federal  tax  reform. 
A  special  message  was  transmitted  by  President  Franldin  D.  Roosevelt 
on  June  19,  1935,  calling  attention  to  the  advantages  possessed  by 
large  corporations,^^  and  recommending  the  enactment  of  a  graduated 
tax  rate  structure  ranging  from  10%  percent  on  the  net  incomes 
of  smaller  corporations  up  to  16%  percent  on  the  net  incomes  of  the 
largest  corporations.  The  President  also  recommended  the  imposition 
of  a  tax  on  dividends  received  from  domestic  corporations,  a  source  of 
corporate  profits  which  had  previously  been  exempt  of  taxation, 
except  during  a  short  period  under  the  income  tax  acts  of  1913-16. 
The  resulting  Revenue  Act  of  1935  introduced  two  new  features  into 
the  Federal  corporation  income  tax  system:  (a)  A  slight  graduation 
of  tax  rates  (ranging  from  12}^  to  15  percent)  according  to  the  size  of 
corporate  net  incomes  which  where  made  subject  to  tax  and  (h)  the 
partial  taxation  of  intercorporate  dividends  (equivalent  at  most  to 
1.5  percent  tax  on  all  dividends  received).  Neither  of  these  provisions 
became  effective  in  this  precise  form  since  the  Revenue  iVct  of  1935 
was  not  scheduled  to  become  operative  until  1936  and  by  that  time 
a  new  revenue  act  had  been  adopted. 

Size  continued  to  be  a  focal  feature  of  the  1936  Revenue  Act.  As 
originally  conceived  in  the  President's  message  sent  to  Congress  on 
March  3,  1936,  and  to  a  substantial  extent  as  drafted  in  the  House  bill 
the  new  tax  plan  contemplated  the  outright  abolition  of  all  existing 
Federal  taxes  based  on  or  related  to  corporate  profits — i.  e.,  the 
normal  tax,  the  capital-stock  tax,  and  the  excess-profits  tax — and  the 
substitution  therefor  of  a  new  tax  of  a  graduated  character  on  that 
part  of  ''corporate  income  (including  dividends  from  other  corpora- 
tions)  which  is  not  distributed  as  earned     *     *     *." 

The  Senate,  however,  was  reluctant  at  one  stroke  to  abandon 
existmg  Federal  taxes  on  corporate  profits — the  normal  tax  on  cor- 
porate income  being  highly  productive  from  a  revenue  viewpoint. 
The  House  bill  was  therefore  drastically  amended  by  the  Senate: 
All  existing  taxes  on  corporate  profits  were  retained  with  some  motii- 
fications  (as  noted  below)  and  superimposed  thereupon  was  a  new 
surtax  on  the  undistributed  profits  of  corporations.  The  new  surtax 
contained  a  severely  graduated  rate  structure,  ranging  from  7  to  27 
percent  of  that  portion  of  corporate  profits  which  was  not  distributed 
durmg  the  year  as  taxable  dividends. 

The  normal  tax  was  modified  by  (a)  limiting  the  credit  for  inter- 
corporate dividends  to  85  percent  instead  of  the  90  percent  allowed 
by  the  1935  act  and  the  100  percent  credit  allowed  under  previous  acts 
(equivalent  at  most  to  a  tax  of  2.25  percent  on  all  dividends  received) 

18  Mr.  Robert  Jackson,  as  Assistant  General  Counsel  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue,  listed  these  ad- 
vantages as  follows: 

_  "(1)  As  buyers  of  commodities  and  services,  the  large  volume  of  their  purchases  gives  the  larger  corpora- 
tions a  bargaining  power  that  often  results  in  price  concessions  which  smaller  concerns  do  not  share. 

"(2)  Through  widely  distributed  branch  plants  and  warehouses  they  are  able  to  effect  important  savings 
in  transportation  costs  and  to  sell  in  a  Nation-wide  market. 

"(3)  Their  large  resources  enable  them  to  buy  up  important  patents,  often  to  pool  these  patents  with  those 
obtained  by  other  large  enterprises,  and  to  carry  on  research  programs,  the  fruits  of  which,  while  of  public  as 
well  as  private  benefit,  accentuate  their  competitive  advantages  over  their  smaller  rivals. 

"(4)  In  many  cases  large  concerns  have  become  of  such  dominating  size  that  they  are  able  to  control  the 
markets  for  their  products,  enabhng  them  to  maintain  prices  that  protect  their  profit  margins. 

"(5)  Large  corporations  possess  distinct  advantages  over  their  smaller  competitors  in  the  facility  and  cost 
of  financing,  for  they  arc  able  to  tap  the  large  reservoirs  of  capital  that  are  made  available  through  the  or- 
ganized financial  markets." 

Ibid.,  pp.  216-217. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  27 

and  (b)  increasing  the  range  of  the  graduated  rate  structure  from 
8  to  15  percent  instead  of  the  narrower  range  specified  by  the  1935  act 
from  12K  to  15  percent.  (The  actual  efficacy  of  this  sliglit  graduation 
in  the  rate  structure  of  the  Federal  normal  corporation  income  tax 
will  be  examined  in  detail  in  chapter  IV.)  Tliese  provisions  remained 
in  effect  through  1937.  The  rate  structure  of  the  excess-profits  tax 
was  also  modified  by  the  1936  act,  which  changed  it  from  a  fiat  rate 
of  5  percent  on  that  portion  of  corporate  income  wliich  exceeded 
12)^  }xnxent  of  the  declared  value  of  capital  stock,  to  a  tax  at  6  percent 
and  12  percent  of  income  in  excess  of  10  percent  and  15  percent,  re- 
spectively, of  declared  capitalization.  It  should  be  pointed  out  that 
the  Senate  amendment  of  the  President's  tax  plan  and  tiie  House  bill 
completely  defeated  one  of  the  major  purposes  claimed  for  the  undis- 
tributed-profits tax — the  equalization  of  business-income  taxes  be- 
tween corporate  and  noncorporate  enterprise. 

The  accumulation  of  criticism  against  the  tax  on  undistributed 
profits  led  Congress  to  all  but  repeal  the  tax  in  1938,  retaining  only  a 
small  stump  of  a  tax  at  2}^  percent  of  the  undistributed  profits  of 
corporations  with  net  income  in  excess  of  $25,000.  In  the  1939  act 
(applicable  to  1940)  the  surtax  on  undistributed  profits  was  com- 
pletely abandoned. 

The  graduated  features  of  the  normal  tax  under  the  1936  Revenue 
Act  were  also  relaxed  to  some  extent  by  the  1938  act.  A  flat-rate  tax  at 
16/2  percent  was  imposed  on  all  corporations  with  net  income  over 
$25,000,  wliile  corporations  with  net  income  below  this  amount 
were  subject  to  a  tax  ranging  from  12}^  to  16  percent  of  net  income. 
Under  the  1938  act  the  range  in  the  graduated  rates  under  the  normal 
tax  was  only  from  12}^  to  16  percent,  or  a  variation  of  3^  percent, 
while  the  rate  graduations  under  the  1936  act  ranged  from  8  to  15 
percent,  or  a  7  percent  variation.  With  the  abandonment  of  the 
surtax  in  the  1939  act,  the  flat-rate  tax  of  16^  percent  of  the  1938  act 
w^as  raised  to  a  flat  rate  of  18  percent  on  all  corporations  with  net 
income  over  $25,000.  The  graduated  range  from  12}^  to  16  percent 
for  corporations  with  net  income  under  $25,000  was  retained  by  the 
1939  act.  The  degressive  rate  structure  of  the  normal  tax  of  the  1938 
and  1939  Revenue  Acts  is  somewhat  comparable  to  the  exemption 
of  the  initial  $3,000  of  net  income  allowed  corporations  with  net 
income  under  $25,000  prior  to  1932. 

Before  the  Revenue  Act  of  1935  the  Federal  corporate  income  tax 
applied  to  all  industries  at  the  same  statutory  rate,  wdth  a  single 
exception  during  the  late  twenties  when  insurance  companies  were 
taxed  at  lower  rates.  Provided  that  the  corporation  was  not  tax- 
exempt  (supra)  and  had  taxable  net  income  (infra),  it  was  subject  to  a 
Federal  tax  on  its  taxable  net  income  at  a  flat  rate,  irrespective  of  the 
nature  of  its  industrial  activities.  The  advent  of  a  graduated  rate 
structure,  however,  did  not  aft'ect  insurance  companies,  banks  and 
trusts,  and  China  Trade  Act  corporations,  which  were  taxed  at  the 
niaximum  rate  (15  percent),  irrespective  of  the  magnitude  of  net 
income.  This  policy  of  imposing  the  maximum  normal  tax  rate 
(which  thus  became  a  flat  rate)  on  certain  members  of  the  financial 
group  of  corporations  has  continued  under  the  Revenue  Acts  of  1938 
(16K  percent)  and  1939  (18  percent). 


28  OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

DEDUCTIONS  FROM  CORPORATE  GROSS  INCOME 

The  profits  upon  which  corporations  are  required  to  pay  taxes  to 
the  Federal  Government  are  essentially  residual  figures,  being  the 
amount  remaining  out  of  corporate  gross  income  after  the  statutory 
deductions  have  been  taken  by  the  taxpayer  and  allowed  by  the  tax 
collector.  These  deductions  vary  in  amount  and  in  their  relative 
significance  to  difierent  types  of  corporations,  reflecting  differences  in 
the  cost  and  capital  structures  of  corporations  as  well  as  in  the  account- 
ing skill  and  the  adequacy  of  corporate  records.  Methods  of  valuating 
inventories  pla;^  an  important  role  in  determining  the  scope  of  ''cost  of 
goods  sold"  claimable  in  various  industries  and  therefore  the  amount 
of  taxable  net  income  remaining  out  of  gross  income. ^^ 

In  the  case  of  certain  deductions  (e.  g.,  percentage  depletion  and 
the  special  4  percent  reserve  deduction  of  life  insurance  conjpanies) 
the  primary  purpose  has  been  to  favor  or  specially  adapt  the  ^x  laws 
to  the  needs  of  particular  industries.  In  other  cases  the  deductions 
have  shown  distinct  tendencies  to  operate  differently  for  corporations 
of  various  sizes  and  in  different  industries.  So  far  as  the  record  shows 
there  has  been  no  conscious  design  of  adapting  the  amount  and  types 
of  deductions  to  the  needs  of  corporations  of  varying  size — aside  from 
the  specific  credit  of  $2,000  to  $5,000  noted  above  in  this  chapter. 
But  this  negative  fact  does  not  gainsay  the  fact  that  in  practice  what 
may  have  been  intended  as  a  uniform  deduction  has  operated  quite 
differently  in  the  case  of  small  corporations  than  in  the  case  of  large 
corporations,  and  vice  versa. 

Chart  V  shows  graphically  statutory  deductions  claimed  by  cor- 
porations of  various  sizes  in  1937.  Each  pyramid  is  divided  into  10 
sectors,  1  for  each  corporate  size  class  (identified  as  Nos.  1-10),  with 
the  small  corporations  on  the  left,  the  large  corporations  on  the  right, 
and  the  medium-sized  corporations  in  between.  The  height  of  any 
given  sector  indicates  the  relative  magnitude  of  the  deduction, 
measured  as  percent  of  total  corporate  receipts.  A  pyramid  sloping 
downward  to  the  right  indicates  an  inverse  relationship  between  the 
magnitude  of  the  deduction  and  corporate  size,  while  a  pj^ramid 
sloping  upward  from  the  left  indicates  a  direct  relationship  between 
the  deduction  and  corporate  size.  A  fairly  even  pyramid  sloping  in 
neither  direction  indicates  that  there  appears  to  be  no  relationship 
between  the  relative  magnitude  of  the  deduction  and  corporate  size. 
An  initial  upward  slope  from  the  left  and  a  final  downward  slope  to  the 
right — forming  a  hurnp  in  the  middle  of  the  pyramid — indicate  that  the 
deduction  was  most  important  to  the  medium-sized  corporations. 

Taking  all  corporations  as  a  group  (including  net  income  and  deficit 
corporations)  in  1937,  these  primary  expense  items — tabulated  as 
cost  of  goods  sold  and  operations  and  including  primarily  the  costs  of 
materials  and  labor — took  approximately  72  to  75  percent  of  the 
total  receipts  of  corporations  with  $1,000,000  or  less,  66  to  69  percent 
of  the  receipts  of  corporations  with  assets  between  $1,000,000  and 
$10,000,000,  64  percent  of  the  receipts  of  corporations  with  assets 
from  $10,000,000  to  $100,000,000,  wliile  the  corporations  with  assets 

"  Of.  Internal  Revenue  Laws,  sec.  22  (c)  and  (d).  No  empirical  data  appear  to  be  available  on  this  sub- 
ject. Prior  to  the  1939  Revenue  Act  the  "last-in-first-out"  method  of  determining  inventories  was  available 
only  to  farmers  and  producer-processors  of  certain  nonfcrrous  metals.  Internal  Revenue  Code,  sec.  22ji(d}. 
Also  see  Regulations  103,  art.  22  (c)  and  (d),  citing  specific  rules  for  dealers  in  securities  (5),  livestock  raisers 
and  other  farmers  (6),  miners  and  manufacturers  (7),  and  retail  merchants  (8).  Section  219  of  the  1939  act 
made  this  method  generallj-  available,  irrespective  of  industry. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  V 


29 


STATUTORY  DEDUCTIONS  FROM  CORPORATE  RECEIPT  BY  SIZE  CLASSES,  1937   (ALL 
CORPORATION  INCOME  TAX  RETURNS  WITH  BALANCE  SHEETS) 


i  2.345678  310 

Cost  of 

SALES 

OPERATIONS 
HB&  MISC. 


I Z34567Q9I0        12345676910 

Taxes 


PAID 


Deprecia- 
tion GB 

Depletion 


'2345676910 

Interest 
paid 


deductions 


ASSET    SIZE    CLASSES 

UNDER     ^50.000 

^50,000   TO  $100,000 

100,000   TO   250,000 

250,000  TO   500,000 

500,000  TO   1,000,000 

.000,000   TO   5,000,000 

5,000,000  TO   10,000,000 

10,000,000  TO   50,000,000  - 

50,000,000  TO  100,000,000 

OVER   100,000,000 


0D-4O-/22 


12345676910 

COMPENSA- 
TION OF 
OFFICERS 


/Z34Se769/0 

RENT  PAID 


/23456789I0 

BAD  .DEBTS 


Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income. 
Department  of  Commerce. 


3Q  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

over  $100,000,000  claimed  only  62  percent  of  their  receipts  as  deduc- 
tions for  cost  of  goods  sold  and  operations.  Substantially  this  same 
pattern  of  an  inverse  relationship  between  the  deductions  for  cost  of 
goods  and  operations  and  corporate  size  was  found  for  substantially 
all  industries  in  1936  except  in  service  and  construction  where  the 
larger  size  classes  reported  the  peak  percentages.  As  cost  of  materials 
becomes  less  important,  the  sales-operating  cost  deduction  declines 
in  relative  magnitude — for  example,  mining  and  public  utilities  where 
the  deduction  (largely  labor  cost)  accounted  for  50-60  percent  of 
total  corporate  receipts.  In  service,  where  the  deduction  consists 
primarily  of  labor  cost,  it  constituted  only  one-third  of  total  receipts 
and  m  fact  was  less  important  than  several  of  the  other  deductions. 

The  specific  deductions  for  interest  paid,  depreciation  and  depletion, 
and  taxes  paid — all  in  the  nature  of  ''overhead  costs" — tend  to  vary 
directly  with  corporate  size  and  thus  offset  in  part  the  inverse  size 
tendency  for  the  primary  expense  items.  The  relative  amount  of 
interest  paid  on  borrowed  capital  rises  from  one-half  of  1  percent  of 
the  total  receipts  of  corporations  with  assets  under  $50,000  and  reach- 
ing 4  percent  of  the  total  receipts  of  corporations  with  assets  over 
$100,000,000.  It  is  obvious,  then,  that  this  deduction  for  interest 
paid,  which  largely  consists  of  payments  to  bondholders  (i.  e.,  creditor- 
investors  in  contrast  to  stockholders  or  equity  investors),  is  a  very 
important  deduction  to  the  large  corporations.^^ 

When  these  size  variations  of  the  interest  deduction  are  analyzed 
industry  by  industry  (see  chart  VI)  however,  the  neat  pattern  of  a 
step-by-step  graduation  with  corporate  size  tends  to  disappear  in 
several  industries.  In  manufacturing  industries  (except  forest 
products,  paper,  and  printing),  trade,  and  construction,  the  size 
variation  is  so  slight  in  magnitude  that  it  is  difficult  to  observe  any 
association  of  the  relative  magnitude  of  interest  payments  with 
corporate  size. 

The  size  variation  of  the  interest  deduction  is  more  pronounced 
among  public  utilities  and  mining  where  the  largest  corporations 
claim  the  relatively  largest  interest  deductions.  The  service  indus- 
tries exhibit  a  somewhat  erratic  size  pattern,  with  the  interest  deduc- 
tion tending  to  increase  rapidly  with  corporate  sizes  up  to  and  includ- 
ing the  seventh  size  class  (assets  $5,000,000  to  $10,000,000)— which 
includes  manj^  hotels,  office  buildings,  and  theaters  whose  debt 
structure  has  been  notoriously  heavy — and  then  tending  to  decline 
sharply  in  magnitude  among  the  largest  size  classes.  The  interest 
pattern  for  finance  is  similarly  erratic,  being  very  important  to  cor- 
porations in  the  fourth  and  fifth  size  classes  (with  assets  from  $25,000 
to  $1,000,000)  and  in  the  tenth  size  class  (assets  of  $100,000,000). 
The  hump  in  the  pattern  caused  by  the  fourth  and  fifth  size  classes  is 
explainable  partly  by  the  fact  that  these  size  classes  probably  include 
a  large  number  of  real  estate  holding  corporations  somewhat  similar 
in  debt  structure  to  the  service  corporations  already  noted. 

The  charges  for  depreciation  and  depletion,  like  the  deduction  for 
interest,  vary  directly  with  corporate  size  when  all  corporations  are 
viewed  as  a  group,  ranging  in  relative  magnitude  from  1.2  to  3.7  per- 
cent.    See  chart  VII.     The  higlily  specific  character  of  the  depletion 

"  The  statutory  vicissitudes  of  this  deduction  are  related,  infra,  pp.  91-92. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  ^l 

deduction  ^^  makes  it  of  substantial  importance  only  to  the  extrac- 
tive industries — mining,  forest  products,  petroleum  and  stone,  clay, 
and  glass — and  of  very  negligible  importance  in  the  remaining  indus- 
tries. A  special  50  percent  depletion  allowance  -^  may  be  claimed  by 
the  discoverers  of  oil  and  gas  wells.  The  direct  variation  between 
the  charges  for  depreciation-depletion  and  corporate  size  may  be  in 
part  a  reflection  of  the  nature  of  the  masurement  of  size  which  is 
based  on  assets,  including,  to  an  increasing  degree  as  corporate  size 
increases,  capital  equipment  upon  which  depreciation  i?  customarily 
charged. 

Wben  these  figures  are  broken  down  industry  by  industry  the 
general  pattern  is  verified  except  in  trade,  where  no  size  variation  is 
apparent,  and  in  construction  where  the  pattern  is  very  erratic. 
Depreciation  is  shown  to  be  of  primary  importance  to  public  utilities, 
and,  in  close  succession,  service  and  again  mining,  with  finance, 
manufacturing,  construction,  and  trade  trailing  behind.  Manufac- 
turing industries  closely  parallel  the  depreciation  percentage  shown 
for  manufacturing  as  a  whole,  with  the  notable  exception  of  petroleum 
and  clothing,  where  depreciation  is  respectively  more  and  less  impor- 
tant than  in  manufacturing  as  a  whole.  It  is  interesting  to  observe 
that  in  several  cases  the  peak  deduction  tends  to  come  in  the  eighth 
and  ninth  size  classes  (assets  from  $5,000,000  to  $50,000,000)  rather 
than  in  the  largest  size  class.  The  same  pattern  is  also  found  in 
most  manufacturing  industries  except  for  beverages,  tobacco,  leather, 
and  printing,  for  which  little  or  no  size  variations  were  noticeable. 

The  deduction  for  taxes  paid  ^^  as  cost  factor  is  relatively  more  im- 
portant to  the  larger  corporations  than  to  the  smaller  or  medium- 
sized  corporations,  in  keeping  taxable  net  income  at  a  minimum. 
Taking  all  corporations  together,  the  pattern  exhibits  a  nice  step-by- 
step  graduation  ranging  from  1.2  percent  in  the  smallest  size  class 
(assets  under  $50,000)  to  3.5  percent  in  the  largest  size  classes  (assets 
over  $100,000,000).  When  figures  are  broken  down  industry  by  in- 
dustry, this  same  pronounced  pattern  is  found  for  public  utilities 
among  the  major  industries  and  for  rubber,  forest  products,  paper, 
printing,  and  metals  among  the  manufacturing  industries.  In  man- 
ufacturing the  peak  rates  are  still  contributed  by  the  larger  size 
classification,  although  not  by  the  very  largest.  In  finance  the 
medium-sized  corporations  reported  the  highest  percentages,  while 
substantially  no  size  variation  could  be  found  for  trade  and  construc- 
tion corporations.  The  high  percentages  for  beverages,  tobacco, 
rubber,  and  petroleum  corporations  reflect  the  special  taxes  to  which 
these  manufacturing  industries  are  subject. 

21  Depletion  was  not  originally  allowed  as  a  deduction  until  1913  when  the  first  revenue  act  under  the 
sixteenth  amendment  specifically  listed  depletion.  See  Stratton's  Independent  Ltd.  v,  Hawbert,  231  U.  S. 
399  (1913).     Of.  Doyle  v.  Mitchell  Bros.  Co.,  247  U.  S.  179  (1918). 

22  See  Internal  Revenue  Laws  (1939),  sec.  114b.  This  special  depletion  deduction  was  introduced  by  sec. 
234  (a)  (9)  of  the  1918  Revenue  Act  (actually  enacted  in  1919)  to  encourage  the  discovery  of  new  oil  and 
gas  wells.  All  discoverers  of  oil  and  gas  wells  on  or  after  March  1, 1913,  may  claim  an  "extraordinary  basis" 
for  the  depletion  deduction,  predicated  "upon  the  fair  market  value  of  the  property  at  the  date  of  the  dis- 
covery" instead  of  original  cost.  In  1921  the  discovery  basis  of  depletion  was  so  limited  that  the  deduction 
could  "not  exceed  the  net  income  computed  without  allowance  for  depletion"  and  in  1924  the  special  deple- 
tion deduction  was  further  limited  ("not  exceed  50  percent  of  the  net  income"). 

23  The  content  of  this  item  is  not  accurately  known  at  present,  although  property  and  pay-roll  taxes  are 
believed  to  constitute  a  major  portion  of  the  deduction. 


32 


CO^X'ENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  VII 


DEPRECIATION  AND  DEPLETION  AS  PERCENT  OF  CORPORATE  RECEIPTS,  BY  SIZE 
CLASSES  AND  INDUSTRIES,  193G  (ALL  CORPORATION  INCOME  TAX  RETURNS  WITH 
BALANCE  SHEETS) 


i*oe         Service      Cohstruc-    Public  Finance     Petroleum    Stone-  Wetals        Voto.^ 

TiON  Utilities  Clay-Glass  Vehiclts 


i6 

14 

z 

ASSET    SIZE    CLASSES 

UNDE?)     SSOOOO 

^50,000    TO   '(00  000 

250,000   TO    500  000 

500,000   TO   :, 000  000 

1,000.000   TO    5.000  000 

5,000,000   TO   10,000.000 

10 

50,000,000   TO  100,000,000 
OVER   100  000.000 

10 
8 
G 
4 
2 

i^ 

k 

^  J     ..i 

r .  i 

pn  1     i 

r     'r  1 

0 

■ 

■  /^j-«,. 

,0    ,,3*%C799 

■0   /sj.ts'sresio  ii3*ie7esio  iimerasio  ig^'tsereiio  /^j-isersi      '^ust 

llJ^SSraSia    113*5673910    IS3tSS7e9IJ 

Food       Beverages      Tobacco        Textiles      Clothing       leather        rubber      Forest  Paper        Printing     Chewicals 

Products 

O  O40U4 

Source:  Computed  from  the  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue. 
Department  of  Commerce. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  33 

Complementary  to  the  deduction  of  taxes  paid  is  that  for  rent, 
which  is  a  necessary  expense  item  for  all  corporations  that  do  not 
own  their  premises  and  therefore  pay  no  real  property  taxes  (pre- 
sumably an  important  ingredient  of  the  ''taxes  paid"  deduction). 
The  rent  deduction  bears  an  inverse  relationship  to  corporate  size, 
steadily  decreasing  in  relative  magnitude  as  corporate  size  increases. 
This  general  pattern  for  all  corporations  is  found  for  substantially  all 
industries  except  trade  (highly  erratic).  The  rent  deduction  is  par- 
ticularly important  to  the  service  industries,  with  finance  and  trade 
trailing  in  third  place.  Rent  is  obviously  unimportant  in  mining 
and  of  oiAj  minor  importance  to  public  utilities,  construction,  and 
manufacturing — for  the  simple  reason  that  these  industries  are 
characterized  by  high  degrees  of  ownership  of  operating  properties. 
The  complementary  relationship  of  the  deduction  for  rent  paid  to 
the  deduction  for  taxes  paid  was  probably  greater  in  the  past  when 
propertj^  taxes  Avere  the  main  component  of  the  tax,  but  this  relation- 
ship may  be  expected  to  diminish  as  nonproperty  taxes  (e.  g.,  pay 
rolls)  increase  in  importance. 

The  most  important  specific  deduction  to  the  small  corporations  is 
that  for  compensation  of  officers.  This  deduction  shows  a  most 
marked  size  pattern  of  an  inverse  character,  ranging  from  6.3  percent 
for  corporations  with  assets  under  $50,000  to  less  than  one-third  of 
1  percent  in  the  case  of  corporations  with  assets  over  $100,000,000. 
This  step-by-step  graduation  downard  in  the  relative  magnitude  of 
the  deduction  as  corporate  size  increases  is  characteristic  of  all  indus- 
tries except  finance  (where  corporations  with  assets  from  $250,000  to 
$1,000,000  report  relative  high  percentages).  The  importance  of  the 
deduction  to  the  smaller  corporations,  however,  can  be  easily  over- 
emphasized, if  it  is  measured  only  in  relative  terms  (as  percentages  of 
total  corporate  receipts)  and  without  reference  to  the  actual  dollar 
amounts  involved.  The  average  dollar  amount  claimed  per  corpora- 
tion as  a  deduction  for  compensation  of  officers  is  very  small — $3,000, 
$5,500,  $7,300,  and  $9,600,  respectively,  for  corporations  in  the  four 
smallest  size  classes.  Assuming  two  or  three  officers  per  corporation, 
it  is  apparent  that  the  amount  of  compensation  of  officers  claimed  as 
a  deduction  is  more  like  wages  than  a  hidden  return  on  capital.^^ 

The  deductions  for  bad  debts  and  capital  losses  are  ver}^  minor  in 
amount,  appearing  relatively  larger  for  the  medium-sized  corporations 
than  for  either  the  largest  or  the  small  corporations.  The  deduction 
for  bad  debts  is  of  substantially  no  significance  to  mining,  manufac- 
turing, and  public  utilities,  and  of  only  minor  significance  to  service, 
construction,  and  trade.  In  this  respect  the  deduction  for  bad 
debts  parallels  the  deduction  for  depletion — it  is  adapted  to  the  special 
operating  characteristics  of  a  particular  industry — namely,  credit  and 
its  failure.  The  reason  for  this  particular  size  variation  of  the  deduc- 
tion of  capital  losses  lies  in  the  essentially  artificial  or  limited  character 
of  the  statutory  deduction,  which  may  not  exceed  $2,000.^'^  In  most 
industries  other  than  finance  and  construction  the  deduction  for 
capital  loss  is  very  negligible,  and  if  foimd  at  all  (usually  not  more  than 

2^  In  the  absence  of  a  frequency  distribution  of  the  amount  of  compensation  claimed  per  officer  per  cor 
poration,  it  is  not  possible  to  characterize  the  deduction  in  more  detail. 

"  This  restriction  has  been  substantially  relaxed  by  the  1939  Revenue  Act,  sec.  212.  which  permits  the  full 
deduction  of  "long-term  capital  losses,"  while  "short-term  capital  losses  shall  be  allowed  only  to  the  extent 
of  short-term  capital  gains,"  with  a  carry-over  of  the  same  to  the  succeeding  taxable  year.  "Short  term" 
loss  or  gain  had  been  previously  defined  in  the  Internal  Revenue  Code  (see  117  (a))  as  referring  to  the  loss  or 
gain  "from  the  sale  or  exchange  of  a  capital  asset  held  for  not  more  than  18  months    •    *    *." 


34  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

one-tenth  of  1  percent  of  total  receipts)  was  usually  claimed  by  the 
small-  and  medium-sized  corporations. 

The  residual  content  of  ''other  deductions"  deprives  this  item  of 
much  of  its  importance  standing  by  itself.  As  defined  in  Statistics  of 
Income,  it  presumably  includes  (1 )  repairs  (including  labor),  (2)  losses 
by  fire  and  storm,  abandonment  of  property,  etc.,  (3)  labor  costs  not 
elsewhere  deducted,  (4)  worthless  stock,  and  (5)  a  miscellany  of  other 
deductions  claimed  (irrespective  of  their  final  validity  under  the  law). 
This  miscellany  may  include  advertising  costs,  commissions,  profes- 
sional services,  heat,  light  and  power,  telephone  and  telegraph,  etc. 
A  substantial  part  of  the  residual  deduction  in  finance,  especially  in 
the  largest  size  class,  reflects  the  special  4-percent  reserve  deduction 
allowed  insurance  companies. ^^ 

\Yhen  the  Corporation  Excise  Tax  Act  of  1909  was  passed  and  also 
when  the  general  income  tax  of  1913  was  under  consideration,  valiant 
attempts  were  made  completely  to  exempt  insurance  companies  from 
Federal  taxation,"  and  were  quite  successful  with  respect  to  mutual 
companies  other  than  life.'^  Life-insurance  companies,  however, 
were  granted  by  the  1909  act  (sec.  38  (2d))  a  special  deduction  for 
*'the  net  addition,  if  any,  required  by  law  to  be  made  within  the  year 
to  reserve  funds."  No  deduction  or  credit,  it  should  be  pointed  out, 
was  originally  permitted  for  interest  received  on  governmental  obliga- 
tions, although  such  income  was  made  tax-exempt  as  of  March  1913. 

Failure  to  specify  the  nature  and  extent  of  this  special  insurance 
deduction  led  to  constant  litigation,  the  consequences  of  which  were 
satisfactory  to  neither  the  tax  collector  nor  to  the  insurance  companies. 
''After  much  consideration.  Congress,  upon  consultation  with  the  life 
insurance  companies  and  with  the  approval  of  at  least  most  of  them"^® 
(including  the  Association  of  Life  Insurance  Presidents),  specified  a  flat 
percentage  (4  percent)  reserve  deduction  m  the  Revenue  Act  of  1921, 
subject  to  a  very  important  proviso — namely,  the  4-percent  reserve 
deduction  should  be  reduced  by  the  amount  of  the  credit  claimed  for 
interest  received  on  tax-exempt  securities.  This  proviso  was  declared 
unconstitutional  by  the  Supreme  Court  in  a  6-3  decision  in  National 
Li/fe  Insurance  Co.  v.  United  States.  Mr.  Justice  McReynolds,  speak- 
ing for  the  majority,  declared  that  such  a  proviso — 

would  destroy  the  guaranteed  exemption.  One  may  not  be  subjected  to  greater 
burdens  upon  his  taxable  property  solely  because  he  owns  some  that  is  free.  No 
device  or  form  of  words  can  deprive  him  of  the  exemption  for  which  he  has  lawfully 
contracted. 3'' 

The  minority,  which  consisted  of  Justices  Brandeis,  Stone,  and  Holmes, 
defined  the  issue  somewhat  differently: 

*  *  *  the  objection  is  not  that  the  plaintiff  [insurance  company]  is  taxed  on 
what  is  exempt,  but  that  others,  who  do  not  hold  tax-exempt  securities,  are  not 
taxed  more.  But  neither  the  Constitution,  nor  any  act  of  Congress,  nor  any  con- 
tract of  the  United  States,  provides  that,  in  respect  to  this  tax,  a  holder  of  tax- 
exempt  bonds  shall  be  better  off  than  if  he  held  onl\'  taxable  securities     *     *     *     ^ 

*  *  *  no  rule  is  better  settled  than  that  provisions  for  tax  exemption,  constitu- 
tional or  contractual,  are  to  be  strictly  construed.^^ 

«  Internal  Revenue  Laws  (1939),  sec.  203. 

'^  See  Congressional  Record,  44:  3980-3981,  4020-4021,  4039,  4053-4055;  50:  1304-1305,  1310-1311,  3802-3803. 
3804.    Also  see  the  hearings  before  the  Senate  Finance  Committee  on  the  1913  Income  Tax  Act,  pp.  1964-2140, 

"  Supra,  p.  22. 

2»  Dissentirsr  opinion  of  Mr.  Justice  Brandeis  in  National  Life  Insurance  Co.  v.  Unifed  States,  277  U.  S.  506 
(1928),  at  p.  523. 

»o  Ibid.,  at  p.  519. 

»'  Ibid.,  pp.  528,  533.  "There  is  a  distinction  between  imposing  a  burden  and  withholding  a  favor."  At 
p.  536. 


Q  G  b  0 

tA  <r>  ir  & 


O  uj 

On 
§^ 

o  n] 

I-  o 

U   UJ 
Q 


b|5§ 


iijjjj.llil 


Q 

z 


|=";5Sg|iJ 


lilll  I 


lis 

pii 


sxa/3:>3bi  3Xt^yodyoo  jo  1/^33 t/^d 


SJ.d  1333a  SMVUOdyOO  JO  jiN30y3<^ 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  35 

The  result  of  this  decision  was  to  allow  life  insurance  companies  to 
claim,  in  addition  to  the  deduction  of  or  credit  for  all  interest  on  tax- 
exempt  securities  and  all  dividends  (only  85  percent  smce  1936)  re- 
ceived from  domestic  corporations,  a  special  deduction  of  4  percent  of 
the  mean  legal  reserve  fund.  This  deduction  in  its  present  form  is 
practically  tantamount  to  exemption  of  life  insurance  companies  from 
Federal  taxation.  In  1937  the  special  reserve  deduction  of  life  insur- 
ance companies  amounted  to  $775,000,000,  while  taxable  net  income 
amounted  to  $2,600,000.  Only  $392,000  were  paid  as  taxes  to  the 
Federal  Govenmient  by  life  insurraice  companies  in  1937. 

The  cunnilativp  effect  of  tl)e  various  statutory  deductions  allowed 
under  the  Revenue  Act  of  1936  upon  total  receipts  (shown  as  100  per- 
cent) of  corporations  of  varying  size  and  in  different  industries  is  shown 
in  chart  VIII  as  a  series  of  pyramids,  each  consisting  of  10  sectors 
representing  size  classes  (identified  by  Nos.  1-10).  The  chart  was 
constructed  by  plotting  at  the  top  (starting  downward  from  100  per- 
cent) the  amount  of  compiled  net  profits  reported  by  corporations  with 
net  income  as  percent  of  total  corporate  receipts  of  all  corporations. 
This  item  is  followed  by  6  main  tj^pes  of  deductions — (1)  interest, 
(2)  depreciation  and  depletion,  (3)  compensation  of  officers,  (4)  taxes 
and  rent  paid,  (5)  miscellaneous  deductions  including  bad  debts,  con- 
tributions, and  net  capital  losses,  and  (6)  cost  of  goods  sold  and  cost  of 
operations,  each  shown  as  percents  of  total  corporate  receipts.  In 
several  size  classes  total  deductions  exceeded  total  receipts,  resulting 
in  ^'deficits"  instead  of  ''profits".  The  "profits"  figure  (shown  at  the 
top  of  tiie  diagram)  excludes  all  deficit  figures  wliich  appear  at  the 
bottom  as  that  part  of  the  item  ''called  cost  of  sales  and  operations" 
which  falls  below  (or  on  the  negative  side  of)  the  zero  line  of  the  dia- 
gram. 

Compiled  net  profits  are  defined  as  the  excess  of  receipts  over 
statutory  deductions.  It  is  therefore  apparent  that  the  smaller  the 
profits  area  on  the  diagram  (shown  at  the  top  of  the  chart),  the  greater 
was  the  cumulative  effect  of  the  various  statutory  deductions  in 
converting  coi:porate  receipts  into  corporate  profits.  Conversely,  the 
larger  the  profits  area,  the  less  the  total  effect  of  the  various  statutory 
deductions. 

The  relative  magnitude  of  the  aggregate  statutory  deductions  from 
corporate  receipts  tends  to  vary  inversely  with  corporate  size.  In 
other  words,  the  cumulated  deductions  claimed  by  the  smaller  cor- 
porations are  relatively  larger  than  those  claimed  by  medium-sized  and 
large  corporations.  The  size  variation  is  relatively  slight  in  trade, 
service,  and  construction  corporations,  while  the  size  factor  is  quite 
marked  in  finance,  public  utilities,  and  mining  corporations,  with 
manufacturing  corporations  falling  between  the  two  groups.  A 
similar  observation  can  be  made  for  the  various  manufacturing  indus- 
tries— the  composite  deductions  are  relatively  largest  on  the  small 
corporations  and  relatively  smallest  on  the  large  corporations.  The 
statutory  deductions  appear  to  have  had  the  least  effect  upon  the 
financial  corporations,  more  than  one-fourth  of  whose  receipts  remained 
(after  subtractiug  all  statutory  deductions)  as  "compiled  net  profits.*' 
The  deductions  made  the  greatest  imprint  on  trade  and  construction, 
only  one-thirtieth  of  whose  receipts  remained  after  the  statutory 
deductions  had  been  allowed.     The  excess  of  receipts  over  deductions 


35  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

was  approximately  one-tenth  for  public  utilities  and  mining,  one- 
fifteenth  for  manufacturing,  and  one- twentieth  for  service.  The 
manufacturing  industries  exhibit  numerous  differences,  with  the  chemi- 
cals and  stone-clay-and-glass  percentages  ranging  highest — con- 
sequently the  composite  deductions  had  lesser  effect— and  the  clothing 
percentage  ranging  lowest — hence  the  composite  deductions  had 
greater  effect  upon  the  latter. 

This  residual  figure  of  corporate  profits  is  taken  as  the  point  of 
departure  for  the  subsequent  analysis  of  the  effects  of  Federal  income 
taxes  upon  corporations.  Before  proceeding  with  this  question 
directly  it  is  advisable  to  examine  certain  problems  arising  out  of  the 
definition  of  the  accounting  period  for  tax  purposes. 

DEFINITION  OF  THE  ACCOUNTING  PERIOD DEDUCTION  OF  PRIOR  YEARS' 

LOSSES 

Empirical  studies  have  shown  that  the  profitability  of  corporations 
varies  both  with  the  size  of  corporations  and  the  character  of  the 
industry.  The  rate  of  return  on  investment  for  those  corporations 
which  make  profits  in  any  given  year  tends  to  be  higher  for  the  smaller 
corporations,  but  over  a  period  of  time  the  larger  corporations  tend  to 
have  profits  with  greater  frequency.  In  other  words,  the  larger  cor- 
porations seldom  suffer  large  losses,  whereas  the  smaller  corporations 
lead  a  very  uneven  career  with  occasional  profits  of  large  magnitude 
and  frequent  intervals  of  losses. ^^ 

Some  industries  make  profits  every  year,  although  the  profits  ma3^ 
seldom  be  large  or  a  high  rate  of  return  on  investment,  while 
other  industries  experience  wide  yearly  fluctuations  in  their  profits. 
When  they  strike  good  they  may  make  considerable  profits,  perhaps 
only  to  have  that  year  followed  by  a  series  of  lean  years  of  deficits. 
If  determined  on  the  basis  of  a  single  year's  operations  and  without 
reference  to  the  corporation's  experience  in  other  years,  it  is  apparent 
that  the  Federal  income  tax  on  corporations  (or  industries)  with  widely 
fluctuating  income  may  operate  somewhat  differently  from  the  tax  on 
corporations  whose  income  remains  fairly  steady  in  character  during 
the  course  of  years.  Whenever  they  make  profits  they  are  taxed,  and 
presumably  taxed  on  the  profits  for  that  year.  When  they  have  losses, 
they  file  their  income-tax  returns  with  the  Government,  and  that  is 
presumably  the  end  of  that.  It  is  obviously  to  their  advantage  for 
the  revenue  laws  to  take  into  account  a  longer  time  period  than  1  year 
in  determining  their  income  and  resultant  tax  liability,  and  presumably 
this  advantage  becomes  more  important  with  the  length  of  the 
accounting  period. 

The  definition  of  the  accounting  period  used  for  determining  tax- 
able income  is  therefore  of  considerable  relevance  to  the  size  problem 
in  Federal  corporate  income  taxation.  Prior  to  1933  and  extending 
as  far  back  as  1918,  the  Federal  revenue  acts  permitted  the  deduction 
of  operating  losses  in  prior  years  from  current  income.  The  back- 
ground out  of  which  this  provision  emerged — as  a  '^response  of  Con- 
gress to  the  hardships  caused  by  the  taxable  year  as  a  unit  of  time" — 
has  been  dramatically  stated  in  Hughes  v.  Commissioner,  as  follows: 

Merchants  and  manufacturers,  and  other  taxpayers  employing  capital  in  their 
pursuits,  had  paid  large  taxes  in  preceding  years  on  paper  profits.     Their  shelves 

32  See  Edwin  B.  George  and  Robert  L.  Tebeau  Profits  and  Dividends:  Big  Business  vs.  Small,  Dun's 
Review,  January  1940,  pp.  11-22. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POAYER  37 

and  warehouses  bulged  with  inventories  whose  values  had  increased  fabulously 
during  the  inflation  period.  The  war  had  ended;  deflation  was  forecast;  war 
trade  was  at  an  end.  A  class  of  taxpayeis  had  paid  taxes  on  incomes  reflected 
by  inventories,  an  income  not  in  fact  realized.  There  was  no  one  to  recoup  them 
the  losses  caused  by  the  shrink  in  the  value  of  their  assets.  This  section  was 
designed  to  permit  such  taxpayers  to  carry  over  such  losses  into  the  2  succeeding 
years. 2^ 

The  provision  of  the  1918  act  arose  clearly  out  of  an  emergency 
situation  and  was  designedly  short-lived,  applying  onl}^  to  the  taxable 
year  October  31,  1918,  to  January  1,  1920.  During  \hat  period  the 
taxpayer  was  allowed  to  deduct  from  the  preceding  year's  income  ^* — 
as  redetermined — any  net  loss  resulting  from  (a)  ''the  operation  of 
an}^  business  regularly  carried  on  by  the  taxpayer"  or  (b)  ''the  bona 
fide  sale  by  the  taxpayer  of  plant,  buildings,  machinery,  equipment, 
or  other  facilities  constructed,  installed,  or  acquired  by  the  taxpayer 
on  or  after  April  6,  1917,  for  the  production  of  articles  contributive 
to  the  prosecution  of  the  present  war."  The  term  "net  loss"  as  de- 
fined included  the  "excess  of  deductions  allowed  by  law  (excluding 
intercorporate  dividends)  over  the  sum  of  the  gross  income  plus  any 
interest  received  free  from  taxation     *     *     *  >?  35 

This  provision  for  net  loss  carry-over  (for  2  years)  was  made  a  gen- 
eral feature  of  the  Federal  income-tax  law  by  the  Revenue  Act  of 
1921  and  remained  so  through  the  year  1931.  The  1918  restrictions 
as  the  offsetting  character  of  intercorporate  dividends  and  Govern- 
ment interest  were  continued  in  the  subsequent  acts,  which  further 
provided  that  in  determining  "net  loss"  no  allowance  should  be  made 
for  depletion  based  solely  on  discovery  values.  Nor  could  net  loss  for 
1  year  produce  "net  loss"  in  succeeding  years.^^  In  1932  the  carry- 
over period  was  reduced  from  2  years  to  1  3^ear,  while  the  deduction 
itself  expired  at  the  end  of  that  year — at  the  verj^  bottom  of  the  great 
depression.  The  Revenue  Act  of  1939  (apphcable  to  1940),  however, 
has  restored  the  limited  deductibility  of  prior  years'  operating  losses 
(2-year  carry-over). ^^ 

During  the  interim  1933-39,  inclusive,  taxable  net  income  was 
determined  on  the  basis  of  a  single  year  without  reference  to  the 
fortunes  of  other  years  (except  for  the  emasculated  undistributed 
profits  tax  in  1938-39).  As  a  consequence  the  only  data  available 
on  the  operation  of  prior  years'  loss  deductions  pertain  to  the  years 
prior  to  1933.  These  data  have  been  summarized  in  charts  IX 
(1926-32,  by  industries)  and  X  (1931-32  by  corporate  size). 

The  deductibility  of  prior  years'  losses  (measured  as  percent  of 
net  income),  it  is  apparent  from  a  quick  inspection  of  chart  IX,  was  a 
matter  of  great  consequence  to  construction  and  mining  corporations, 
the  taxable  net  income  of  which  was  reduced  by  more  than  13  percent 
in  1932.  The  deduction  was  unimportant  to  public  utilities,  where 
it  usually  reduced  their  taxable  net  income  by  only  1  to  2  percent  or 
less.  Its  importance  to  financial  corporations  sharply  increased  with 
the  course  of  the  depression,  more  rising  from  2.2  percent  in  1929  to 
7.1  percent  in  1932.  Its  role  in  manufacturing  increased  only  slightly, 
rising  from  2.2  percent  in  1926  to  4.3  percent,  and  with  the  advent 

33  38  F.  (2d)  755  (1930),  at  p.  758. 

34  Any  excess  could  be  deducted  from  the  income  of  the  succeeding  year. 

35  Sec.  234(a). 

36  Sec.  204.    Also  see  Regulations  62,  art.  1601. 

37  Sec.  122.    The  1938-39  changes  in  the  accounting  methods  for  taking  inventories  were  intended  to 
reduce  fluctuations  and  insofar  serve  the  same  purpose  as  loss  carry-over  provisions. 

262698— 41— No.  9 4 


38  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

of  the  depression  (1930)  actually  declined  below  the  1926-29  figure. 
Its  role  in  trade  and  service  also  increased  with  the  course  of  the 
depression,  somewhat  paralleling  manufacturing — experiencing  a  de- 
cline in  1930 — but  the  use  of  prior  years'  losses  in  those  industries 
was  quite  unspectacular. 

The  prosaic  course  of  the  prior  years'  loss  line  in  manufacturing  is 
spectacularly  departed  from  by  several  manufacturing  industries, 
particularly  in  rubber,  textiles,  forest  products,  and  food  and  beverages. 
In  rubber  and  food-beverages  the  deduction  for  prior  years'  losses 
showed  a  tendency  to  soar  upward  as  the  depression  became  intensi- 
fied, rising  as  high  as  15  percent  of  net  income  in  the  former  case. 
Both  textiles  and  forest  products  were  characterized  by  considerable 
irregularity  during  the  entire  period  (1926-32)  for  which  data  are 
available."  Printing,  leather,  chemicals,  metals  (except  in  1928), 
stone-clay-glass,  and  paper  appear  fairly  regular  3'ear  by  year  in  the 
amount  of  losses  claimed  as  a  deduction  from  net  income.  Tobacco 
made  substantially  no  use  of  the  deduction. 

The  importance  of  the  prior  years'  loss  deductions  to  corporations 
of  varying  size  in  1931  and  1932  is  shown  as  a  series  of  pyramids  in 
chart  X  (each  containing  9  sectors  representing  size  classes).  The 
relative  magnitude  of  the  deduction  is  measured  as  percent  of  net 
income  before  the  allowance  for  the  prior  years'  losses.  The  size  of 
these  percentages  shows  the  relative  degree  by  which  net  income  was 
reduced  by  the  allowance  of  this  deduction.  The  niagnitude  of  the 
prior  years'  loss  deduction  tends  to  vary  inversely  with  size — that  is, 
the  smaller  corporations  tended  to  claim  relatively  larger  prior  years' 
losses  than  did  the  larger  corporations,  particularly  in  manufacturing 
generally,  trade,  and  construction,  and  to  a  lesser  degree,  in  finance 
and  public  utilities.  Among  manufacturing  industi'ies  this  observa- 
tion is  also  applicable  to  tobacco,  leather,  paper,  printing,  chemicals, 
stone-clay -glass,  and  metals. 

But  there  were  some  very  notable  exceptions  to  this  general  pattern, 
particularly  in  1931,  when  the  relatively  largest  deductions  for  prior 
years'  losses  were  claimed  by  the  largest  corporations,  as  in  mining 
(1931)  and  service  (1932),  and  among  the  manufacturing  industries, 
in  food  and  beverages  (1932),  textiles  (1931),  rubber  (1932),  and  forest 
products  (1931) .  These  exceptions  are  notable  because  of  the  relative 
magnitudes  involved.  The  largest  loss  deduction  claimed  by  small 
corporations,  among  the  major  industries  was  4.7  percent  of  net  income 
(construction  corporations  with  assets  under  $50,000  in  1932)  while 
the  largest  loss  deduction  claimed  by  the  biggest  corporations  was 
92  percent  (mining  corporations  with  assets  over  $50,000,000  in  1931) 
or  approximately  20  times  as  much  as  that  claimed  by  the  smaller 
corporations.  Likewise  among  manufacturing  industries  the  largest 
deductions  for  small  corporations  was  48  percent  of  net  income  (rubber 
corporations  with  assets  from  $100,000  to  $250,000  in  1931)  as  against 
78  percent  (rubber  corporations  with  assets  from  5  to  10  million 
dollars  in  1931)  of  the  net  income  of  larger  corporations. 

These  illustrations  suggest  that  the  prior  years'  loss  deduction  was 
of  very  substantial  importance  to  large  corporations  in  particular  in- 
dustries (e.  g.,  mining,  rubber,  and  lumber)  where  the  cyclical  fluctu- 
ations of  the  industry  more  than  offset  the  size  factor.  Conversely, 
the  generahzation  (stated  at  the  outset  of  this  section)  that  the  smaller 
corporations  tend  to  have  lower  chances  of  profits  in  the  long  run  may 
not  be  applicable  to  highly  fluctuating  industries. 


Chart  IX 

DEDUCTION  OF  PRIOR  YEARS'  LOSSES  AS  PERCENT  OF  TAXABLE  NET  INCOME  BY  INDUSTRIES.  1926-32  (RETURNS  WITH  NET  INCOME  ONLY) 

1 1 

MANUFACTURING  INDUSTRIES 

u 


■' ] 

MAJOR  INDUSTRIES 

CONSTRUC- 

ION 

/ 

l\ 

; 

y 

^ ' 

/ 

-^•  — 

\ 

f. 

/  - 

SERVICE 
TRADE 

"\ 

^'^ 

/' 

-v. 

'    / 

/ 

MANUFACHJ 

RINS 

x 

-^ 

\y 

/ 
/ 

/' 

^ 

— 

N 

\   '\ 

/ 

,.-• 

, ' 

PUBLIC   UTILITIES 

1327  1928  1329  1930  1331  19^2 


Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 
Department  of  Commerce. 


1926  1927  1928 


DO .40 -139 

-41— No.  9      (Face p.  38)      No.  1 


\ 

1  ■^"^^ 

"n. 

M: 

-^ 


DEDUCTION  OF  PKIOR  YEARS'  LOSSES  AS  PERCENT  OF  TAXABLE  NET  INCOME,  BY  SIZE  CLASSES  AND  INDUSTRIES  1931-32  (RETURNS  WITH  NET  INCOME  ONLY) 


PESCENTAGE   CLAIMED   FOR    BOTH  YEARS 
ADDITIONAL    PERCENTAGE    CLAIMED     IN     1332  OVER     1931 
ADDITIONAL    PERCENTAGE    CLAIVEO     IN     1931    OVER     1932 
LESS    THAN    .0^ 


Source:  Computed  from  the  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue. 
Department  of  Commerce. 


CHAPTER  III 

FEDERAL  TAX  TREATMENT  OF  HOLDING  COMPANIES  AND 
RELATED  FORMS  OF  INTERCORPORATE  AFFILIATION 
(CONSOLIDATED  RETURNS) 

To  what  extent  are  the  profits  of  corporations  of  varying  sizes  and 
industries  affected  by  Federal  income  taxes? 

The  formulation  of  this  question  raises  at  least  two  problems  of 
definition — what  taxes  and  what  profits?  The  tax  item  has  been 
defined  as  including  only  taxes  paid  by  corporations  directly  to  a 
governmental  body — in  this  instance  to  Federal  collectors  of  internal 
revenue.^  For  the  purpose  of  this  and  the  immediately  following 
chapter,  the  tax  item  has  been  further  defined  to  include  only  the 
so-called  "normal"  corporation  income  tax;  succeeding  chapters  deal 
with  the  effect  of  the  excess-profits  and  capital-stock  taxes  and  the 
surtax  on  undistributed  profits,  and  the  composite  effects  of  all  four 
Federal  taxes  based  upon  or  related  to  corporate  profits.  The  profits 
item  has  been  defined  as  including  all  income  otherwise  available 
(that  is,  before  the  payment  of  Federal  income  taxes)  to  the  corpora- 
tion for  (a)  distribution  of  dividends  to  stockholders  or  (b)  reinvest- 
ment in  or  by  a  corporation  ("undistributed  profits"). 

THE    CORPORATE    WORLD 

If  corporations  were  separate  entities  and  unrelated  to  one  another — 
except  in  a  bargaining  capacity  "at  arms'  length" — these  definitions 
of  the  terms  of  the  inquiry  would  probably  suffice  without  more  ado. 
Ever  since  1888,  however,  when  the  State  of  New  Jersey  authorized 
corporations  chartered  under  its  laws — and,  by  the  grace  of  the  con- 
stitutional doctrine  of  comity,  operating  anywhere  in  the  United 
States — to  acquire  stock  in  other  corporations,  the  members  of  the 
corporate  system  have  become  closely  interrelated.  Prior  to  this 
step  taken  by  the  State  of  New  Jersey,  corporations  were  almost 
invariably  owned  and  controlled  by  natural  persons  as  stockholders.^ 

With  the  rapid  and  widespread  use  of  this  new  corporate  power, 
which  was  rapidly  authorized  by  other  State  legislatures,^  corpora- 
tions have  become,  to  no  small  degree,  owners  of  themselves.  Accord- 
ing to  the  most  recent  statistics  (1934-37)  collected  on  a  comparable 
base  in  this  respect,  a  very  substantial  part  of  all  cash  dividends  paid 

1  This  definition  was  made  at  the  outset  of  the  studies  on  the  ground  that  only  such  taxes  as  were  paid 
directly  to  the  Government  can  be  accurately  known  for  any  tax-paying  unit  or  aggregate  of  units  for  any 
given  time  period. 

2  Bonbright  and  Means  record  a  handful  of  cases  where  corporations  were  specifically  authorized  by  their 
charter  of  incorporation  to  own  stock  in  other  corporations,  including  Baltimore  &  Ohio  Railroad  (1832), 
Pennsylvania  Railroad  (1850),  Western  Union  Telegraph  Co.  (1804),  American  Bell  Telephone  Co.  (1880), 
and  some  forty  odd  corporations  specially  chartered  by  the  Pennsylvania  Legislature  between  1868  and  1872, 
among  which  were  the  Pennsylvania  Co.  (probably  the  first  pure  holding  company)  and  South  Improve- 
ment Co.    See  "Holding  Companies,"  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  7:404.. 

3  "In  a  period  of  40  years  the  holding  company,  which  had  been  regarded  as  undesirable  and  contrary  to 
public  policy  except  under  unusual  conditions,  was  made  by  most  States  an  acceptable  and  legal  practice." 
Ibid. 

39 


40  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

out  by  American  corporations  have,  in  fact,  been  received  b}^  them- 
selves as  corporate  stockholders  in  one  another.  In  1934  dividend 
income  from  domestic  corporations  constituted  45.6  percent  of  all 
cash  dividends  distributed  by  American  corporations;  in  1935,  50.7 
percent;  in  1936,  36.5  percent;  and  in  1937,  34.4  percent.^  From  these 
figures  it  may  be  concluded  that  at  least  one-third  to  one-half  of  the 
profits  reported  by  the  half-million  corporations  of  the  United  States, 
when  distributed,  are  paid  to  and  received  by  American  corporations.* 

Intercorporate  investments  have  grown  not  only  in  magnitude — 
so  that  approximately  half  of  corporate  America  is  owned  by  the  other 
half  of  corporate  America — but  also  in  complexity.  By  strategically 
selecting  the  kind  and  amount  of  stock  to  be  held  in  other  corporations, 
one  corporation  may  in  time  control  the  policies  and  activities  of 
several  corporations,  representing  investments  vastly  larger  than  the 
original  contributions  of  the  controlling  corporation  or  '4iolding 
company,"  as  it  rapidly  became  known. ^ 

Essentially  this  new  corporate  device  known  as  the  holding  com- 
pany, or  some  gradation  thereof,  was  simple  in  purpose  and  nature, 
although  its  consequences  in  practice  were  to  make  an  already  com- 
plicated corporate  world  so  complex  that  words  or  two-dimensional 
charts  are  usually  inadequate  to  describe  it.  The  simple  purpose  of 
the  holding  compan}^  was  to  control  and  exercise  overhead  manage- 
ment of  the  '' properties  of  two  or  more  heretofore  independent  corpo- 
rations," with  minimum  risk  and  investment.  When  carried  to  several 
degrees,  this  teclinique  of  industry  control  has  been  appropriately 
described  as  ''pyramidal,"  with  the  holding  company  sitting  at  the 
top  of  the  pyramid  holding  successively  small  blocks  of  stock  in  the 
underlying  layers  of  the  pyramid  and  controlling  the  activities  of  the 
entire  pyramid. 

Where  each  company  in  the  series  has  bonds  and  nonvoting  preferred  stock  out- 
standing, the  reduction  in  the  investment  necessary  for  control  diminishes  even 
more  rapidly,  so  that  a  pyramid  involving  three  holding  companies  will  allow,  say, 
a  $1,000,000  investment  in  a  top  holding  company  to  control  a  billion-dollar  operat- 
ing company.  The  investment  necessary  for  control  may  be  made  even  smaller 
by  issuing  nonvoting  common  stock  or  stock  with  limited  voting  power. ^ 

The  business  advantages  of  the  holding  technique  are  obvious* 
Bonbright  and  Means  have  summarized  them  as  follows: 

Ease  of  organizing  the  combination. 

Ease  of  perpetuating  control  in  the  hands  of  the  organizer  by  means  of  stock 
pyramiding. 

Ability  to  combine  enterprise  that  could  not  be  legally  fused  by  direct  ownership. 

Secrecy  of  the  fact  of  the  combination  and  its  financial  accounts  and  operations. 

Freedom  from  governmental  regulation. 

Decentralization  of  management. 

Insulation  of  liabilities. 

Ease  of  divorcing  the  properties.^ 

It  is  manifest  from  this  formidable  enumeration  that  industrial 
integration  has  been  greatly  facilitated  by  the  holding-company 
technique  without  involving  either  the  costs  or  the  difficulties  of  out- 

*  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  j'ears. 

*  These  relationships  of  dividend  income  and  distributed  dividends,  of  course,  vary  with  corporate  size. 
In  1937  for  every  hundred  dollars  cash  dividends  distributed  by  the  largest  corporations  (with  assets  over 
$100,000,000)  those  same  corporations  received  $52  as  dividends,  while  the  smaller  corporations  (with  assets- 
under  $250,000)  received  as  dividends  only  $6  to  $9  for  every  hundred  dollars  distributed  as  cash  dividends. 

«  See  Bonbright  and  Means,  The  Holding  Company.  For  concrete  illustrations  of  intercorporate  stock 
ownership  and  control,  see  the  reports  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  on  public-utility  holding  companies- 
and  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission  on  investment  trusts. 

'  Bonbright  and  Means,  "Holding  Companies,"  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  7:406. 

8  The  Holding  Company,  pp.  30-40. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  41 

right  merger  or  consolidation  and  yet  retaining  all  the  flexibihty  of 
separate  operating  units.  Such,  in  brief,  without  commendation  or 
condemnation,  are  the  purposes  and  techniques  of  intercorporate 
investment.® 

CONSOLIDATED  CORPORATE  INCOME-TAX  RETURNS!  ORIGIN  AND  HISTORY 

Prior  to  1934-36  the  Federal  revenue  acts  substantially  facilitated 
the  practice  and  growth  of  intercorporate  affiliations  by  allowing  the 
members  of  an  interaffiliated  corporate  system  to  file  a  consoliclated 
income-tax  return  in  wliich  the  losses  of  constituent  members  could  be 
offset  against  the  profits  of  other  members.  The  exemption  from 
Federal  corporate  income  taxation  of  all  dividend  income  received 
from  other  domestic  corporations  subject  to  tax,  w^hich  will  be  ex- 
amined in  the  following  chapter,  is  another  example  of  the  Federal 
revenue  acts  doing  little  or  notiiing  (prior  to  1936)  to  hinder  the 
prevalence  of  holding  companies  and  related  forms  of  intercorporate 
affiliation. 

The  basic  industrial  unit  for  Federal  corporate-income-tax  purposes 
was  originally  the  corporate  entity  ''as  if  it  were  in  no  way  related  to 
any  other  corporation. "^°  Starting  in  1917,  however,  the  Federal 
revenue  laws  took  special  cognizance  of  the  fact  that  corporations 
frequently  were  closely  interrelated  through  the  ownership  of  the 
stock  of  one  another  and  the  interlocking  representation  of  common 
interest.  In  the  first  period  of  this  development  (1917-21)  all  the 
members  of  an  interlocking  corporate  system  were  required  to  file 
with  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue  a  consolidated  income-tax 
return  as  if  they  were  a  single  legal-economic  entity,  without  regard 
to  intermember  activities  within  the  system.  In  1921  the  mandatory 
requirement  was  converted  into  a  privilege  of  the  interaffiliated 
corporations  to  file  a  consolidated  return  for  the  entire  system,  if  they 
so  should  choose. 

With  the  coming  of  the  depression  and  the  resultant  decimation  of 
income  taxes  as  producers  of  Federal  revenue,  the  consolidated  tax- 
returns  device  became  subject  to  intense  criticism,  which  initially 
reflected  itself  in  the  imposition  of  a  tax  at  a  slightly  higher  statutory 
rate  (three-fourths  of  1  percent  in  1932  and  1  percent  in  1933)  on 
€onsolidated  returns  and  then  in  the  outright  repeal  of  consolidated 
returns  in  1934,  with  the  exception  of  ''common  carrier  by  railroad.'^ 
The  unit  of  Federal  corporate  income  taxation  has  again  become  the 
corporation  ^^  as  such,  with  the  exception  just  noted. 

(a)  Mandatory  consolidation  of  income-tax  returns  jor  inter-affiliated 
corporations.^^ — The  enactment  of  an  excess-profits  tax  at  steeply 
graduated  rates  (ranging  from  20  to  60  percent)  in  1917  (see  ap- 
pendix A),  of  course,  brought  in  their  tow  aggravated  administrative 
problems.  By  regulation  it  was  promptly  provided  that  "wherever 
necessary  to  more  equitably  determine  the  invested  capital  or  taxable 

»  See  also  testimony  of  Professor  Fetter  before  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  Hearings, 
Part  5,  pp.  1667-1677. 
If  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue,  Regulations  33  (under  the  1916  Revenue  Act),  art.  207. 

11  Regulations  101  (under  the  Revenue  Act  of  1938)  define  "corporations"  as  including  not  only  "the 
artificial  entity  usually  known  as  a  corporation,  but  *  *  *  also  an  association,  a  trust  classed  as  an 
association,  because  of  its  nature  or  its  activities,  a  joint  stock  company,  an  insurance  company,  and  certain 
kinds  of  partnerships,"  art.  901-1.    For  further  definitions  see  the  remaining  sections  of  art.  901. 

12  The  American  Institute  of  Accountants,  iu  advocating  the  use  of  consolidated  returns  prior  to  the 
Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue  regulations  under  the  1917  act,  stated  that  taxes  would  then  be  "based  on  the 
real  facts  and  determined  by  the  relation  between  true  income  and  true  investment  of  the  companies  as 
a  whole."    Quoted  in  Paul  and  Mertens,  Federal  Income  Taxation,  4-420n, 


42  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

income,"  the  Commissioner  of  Internal  Revenue  ''may  require 
corporations  classed  as  affiliates  under  article  77  to  furnish  a  con- 
solidated return  of  net  income  and  invested  capital."  ^^  Article  77 
provided  that  affiliation  would  be  deemed  to  exist: 

1.  When  one  such  corporation  owns  directly  or  controls  through  closely  affili- 
ated interests,  or  by  nominee  or  nominees,  all  or  substantially  all  of  the  stock  or 
stocks  of  the  other  or  ethers,  or  when  substantially  all  the  stock  of  two  or  more 
corporations  is  owned  by  the  same  individual  or  partnership,  and  both  or  all  such 
corporations  are  engaged  in  the  same  or  closely  related  business;  or 

2.  When  one  such  corporation  (a)  buys  from  or  sells  to  another  products  or 
services  at  prices  above  or  below  the  current  market,  thus  effecting  an  artificial 
distribution  of  profits,  or  (6)  in  any  way  so  arranges  its  financial  relationships 
with  another  corporation  as  to  assign  to  it  a  disproportionate  share  of  net  income 
or  invested  capital.'* 

The  need  for  requiring  consolidated  tax  returns  was  stated  by  the 
Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue  as  follows: 

Otherwise  opportunity  would  be  afforded  for  the  evasion  of  taxation  by  the 
shifting  of  income  through  price  fixing,  charges  for  services,  and  other  means  by 
which  income  could  be  arbitrarily  assigned  to  one  or  another  unit  of  the  group. 
In  other  cases  without  a  consolidated  return  excessive  taxation  might  be  imposed  as 
a  result  of  purel.y  artificial  conditions  existing  between  corporations  within  a 
controlled  group. '^ 

The  Senate  Finance  Committee  (reporting  on  the  1918  Revenue  Act) 
favored  the  consolidated  tax  return  ''not  primarily  because  it  operates 
to  prevent  evasion  of  taxes  or  because  of  its  effect  upon  the  revenue 
but  because  the  principle  of  taxation  as  a  business  unit,  what  in 
reality  is  a  business  unit,  is  sound  and  equitable  and  convenient  both 
to  the  taxpayer  and  to  the  Government."  ^^ 

The  Revenue  Act  of  1918  specifically  provided  that  interaffiliated 
corporations  "shall  make  a  consolidated  return  of  net  income  and 
invested  capital,"  ^''  for  the  purpose  of  tax  computation  upon  the 
basis  of  such  return.  Changing  the  definition  of  affiliation  somewhat 
from  that  found  in  the  Commissioner's  regulations,  the  statute 
provided  that  corporations — 

*  *  *  shall  be  deemed  to  be  affiliated  (1)  if  one  corporation  owns  directly 
or  controls  through  closely  affiliated  interests  or  by  a  nominee  or  nominees  sub- 
stantially all  the  stock  of  the  other  or  others,  or  (2)  if  substantially  all  the  stock  of 
two  or  more  cori)orations  is  owned  or  controlled  by  the  same  interests. i^ 

An  atternpt  to  confine  consolidated  tax  returns  to  "corporations 
engaged  in  the  same  or  related  business,"  as  specified  in  the  Com- 
missioner's regulations,  was  unsuccessful. 

The  loose  definition  of  "affiliation"  naturally  gave  rise  to  difficult 
problems  of  interpretation.^^  Regulations  45  (under  the  1918  act) 
required  consolidation  in  all  cases  involving  control  of  "95  percent  or 
more  of  the  outstanding  voting  capital  stocl^  (not  including  stock  in 
the  treasury)"  and  contemplated  tiiat  consolidation  might  be  required 
in  other  cases  where  control  was  considerably  less.^° 

(6)  Consolidation  made  optional  with  the  tax-paying  corporation. — 
Under  the  1921  Revenue  Act  the  managers  of  an  mteraffiliatod  cor- 

>»  Regulations  41,  art.  78. 

"  Tho  Commissioner's  action  was  specifically  ratified  by  the  1921  Revenue  Act,  sec.  1331. 

>»  Regulations  45.  art.  631. 

18  65th  Cong.,  30th  sess.,  S.  Rept.  617,  p.  819. 

1'  Sec.  240  (a).  Note  that  the  "shall"  was  construed  as  mandatory  in  effect.  See  also  Regulations  45 
arts.  631-638. 

18  Sec.  240  (b). 

i»  For  a  list  of  such  questions,  see  the  1928  Report  of  the  Joint  Committee  on  Internal  Revenue  Taxation, 
pp.  65-66. 

'«  Art.  633.    Tax  Board  cases  have  gone  as  far  down  as  85  percent.    See  Paul  and  Mertens,  op.  cit.,  4:  523. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  43 

porate  system  were  permitted  to  elect  whether  to  file  separate  tax 
retm'ns  or  to  make  a  consolidated  tax  return.  But  once  having  made 
an  election,  the  same  became  binding  on  all  the  members  of  the  cor- 
porate system,  which  must  thereafter  file  its  tax  returns  ''upon  the 
same  basis  unless  permission  to  change  the  basis  is  granted  by  the 
Commissioner."  ^^  No  substantial  change  was  made  in  the  statutory 
definition  of  afhliation.^^ 

The  Revenue  Act  of  1924  defined  ''affiliation"  with  greater  preci- 
sion, specifying  that  "control"  resulted  "(1)  if  one  corporation  owns 
at  least  95  percent  of  the  voting  stock  of  the  other  or  others,  or  (2) 
if  at  least  95  percent  of  the  voting  stock  of  two  or  more  corporations 
is  owned  b}^  the  same  interests."  -^  The  words  "substantially  all" 
were  thus  succeeded  by  an  arithmetic  figure  and  "control"  became 
limited  to  "own."  Some  vagueness  about  "voting  stock"  still 
remained  to  be  corrected  in  the  1926  act.^"* 

Opposition  to  the  device  of  consolidated  returns  began  to  be  voiced. 
In  the  debate  on  the  1924  Revenue  Act,  Senator  Smoot  contended 
that  consolidated  tax  returns  played  an  important  role  in  the  current 
phase  of  destructive  competition  in  the  lumber  industry. ^^  By  rais- 
ing the  control  figure  from  80  percent  (as  specified  by  the  House)  to 
95  percent,  this  danger  was  believed  accounted  for.  During  the  con- 
sideration of  the  1928  Revenue  Act  criticism  of  consolidated  tax  re- 
turns again  flared  up,  and  in  fact  the  opposition  was  sufficiently 
strong  for  the  House,  supported  to  a  substantial  extent  by  the 
report  of  the  Joint  Committee  on  Internal  Revenue  Taxation,  to 
vote  for  the  abolition  of  the  privilege  of  filing  consolidated  returns  in 
order  to  prevent  unfair  competition  and  price  cutting  via  taxation. 
In  the  Senate  Finance  Committee,  however,  the  consolidated  tax 
returns  were  warmly  defended: 

To  refuse  to  recognize  this  situation  and  to  require  for  tax  pur])oscs  the  break- 
ing up  of  a  single  business  into  its  constituent  parts  is  just  as  unreasonable  as  to 
require  a  single  corporation  to  report  separately  for  tax  purposes  the  gains  from 
its  sales  department,  from  its  manufacturing  activities,  from  its  investments, 
and  from  each  and  every  one  of  its  agencies.  *  *  *  Your  committee  believes 
that  rather  than  departing  from  business  practices  and  standards  our  revenue 
laws  should  be  brought  nearer  to  a  recognition  of  them.2« 

The  revenue  lav/  of  1928  retained  consolidated  tax  returns  albeit 
in  somewhat  altered  form.  The  rule-making  authority  of  the  Com- 
missioner of  Internal  Revenue  was  greatly  increased.  A  separate 
regulation  series  (75)  comprising  24  printed  pages  was  issued  on  con- 
solidated tax  returns,  whereas  previously  only  a  few  sections  of  three 
to  four  pages  of  the  general  series  on  income-tax  regulations  had 
sufficed.  The  mere  filing  of  a  consolidated  tax  return  by  an  affiliated 
group,  it  was  stipulated  in  the  new  regulations,  operated  as  its  con- 
sent to  all  regulations  prescribed  by  the  Commissioner.^^  The  defini- 
tion of  "affiliation"  was  refined  as  follows: 

*  *  *  an  "affiliated  group"  means  one  or  more  chains  or  corporations  con- 
nected through  stock  ownership  with  a  common  parent  corporation  if  (1)  at  least 
95  percent  of  the  stock  of  each  of  the  corporations  (except  the  common  parent 

21  See  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue,  Regulations  62,  arts.  631-638.  Note,  however,  that  each  successive 
revenue  act  (1924,  1926,  1928,  and  1932)  afforded  new  opportunities  for  election. 

"  Rej!:ulations  02  (under  the  1921  act)  raised  the  lower  limit  of  potential  affiliability  to  70-percent  control. 

»  See  240  (c).  Chain  Trade  Act  corporations  were  excepted. 

'<  "As  used  in  this  subdivision  the  term  'stock'  does  not  include  nonvoting  stock  which  Is  limited  and 
preferred  as  to  dividends,"  sec.  240  (d). 

"  Cong.  Rec,  65:71.30. 

2«  70th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  S.  Rept.  960,  pp.  15-24. 

"  In  1932  this  clause  was  enacted  by  the  revenue  act,  sec.  1 11  (a). 


44  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

corporation)  is  owned  directly  by  one  or  more  of  the  other  corporations;  and  (2) 
the  common  parent  corporation  owns  directly  at  least  95  percent  of  the  stock  of 
at  least  one  of  the  other  corporations. ^^ 

Ownership  by  common  ''interests"  (e.  g.,  by  stockholders) — so- 
called  class  B  affihates — no  longer  sufficed;  to  permit  the  filing  of  a 
consoHdated  tax  return,  direct  ownership  by  the  corporation  or 
corporations  was  required.  A  major  change  in  the  nature  of  the 
tax  liability  of  the  affiliated  group  and  its  member  was  effected  by 
article  15  (a)  of  the  Commissioner's  regulations,  which  provided  that 
the  parent  and  each  subsidiary  were  severally  liable  for  the  tax. 

In  the  course  of  the  debate  on  the  Revenue  Act  of  1932,  the  con- 
solidated tax  return  device  was  again  scored  for  its  competitive  abuse 
by  chain  stores  and  utilities.^^  The  House  was  especially  critical, 
suggesting  that  consolidated  tax  returns,  if  permitted  at  all,  must  be 
subject  to  an  additional  tax  of  Iji  percent.  The  Senate,  however, 
insisted  on  paring  the  differential  rate  down  to  three-fourths  of  1 
percent. ^"^ 

(c)  Abolition  of  consolidated  returns  in  1934,  "^i^  certain  exceptions. — 
The  growing  opposition  against  consolidated  tax  returns  reached  its 
chmax  during  the  consideration  of  the  Revenue  Act  of  1934.  To  the 
charge  of  competitive  unfairness,  which  had  been  aired  on  previous 
occasions  (notably  in  1928  and  1932),  wxre  now  added  the  following 
specific  criticism  of  the  consolidated  returns  privilege: 

It  cannot  be  denied  that  the  privilege  of  filing  consolidated  returns  is  of  sub- 
stantial benefit  to  the  large  groups  of  corporations  in  existence  in  this  country. 
This  is  especially  true  in  depression  years,  for  the  effect  of  the  consolidated  return 
is  to  allow  the  loss  of  one  corporation  to  reduce  the  net  income  and  tax  of  another, 
and  during  a  depression  more  losses  occur.  Another  effect  of  the  consolidated 
return  may  be  to  postpone  tax.  This  is  because  there  is  no  profit  recognized  for 
tax  purposes  on  intercompany  transaction,  and  profits  on  a  product  of  the  con- 
solidated group,  passing  through  the  hands  of  the  different  members  of  the  group, 
are  not  taxed  until  the  product  is  disposed  of  to  persons  outside  the  group. 

In  the  past,  when  any  corporation  could  carry  forw^ard  a  net  loss  from  one  year 
to  another,  the  consolidated  group  did  not  have  such  a  great  advantage  over  the 
separate  corporation.  Now  that  this  net  loss  carry-over  has  been  denied,  the 
advantages  of  the  consolidated  return  is  much  greater  on  a  comparative  basis. ^^ 

Despite  an  estimate  that  the  elimination  of  consolidated  returns 
would  result  in  ''an  annual  increase  in  revenue  of  $20,000,000,"^^ 
the  Treasury  favored  the  retention  of  consolidated  returns: 

*  *  *  there  are  considerable  savings  to  the  Treasury,  as  well  as  to  taxpayers, 
in  the  present  arrangement.  The  administration  of  the  law  is  simpler  since  it 
conforms  to  established  practice.  The  Treasury  need  deal  with  only  one  corpora- 
tion, the  parent.  On  the  taxpayer's  side,  the  requirement  of  separate  returns 
would  cause  largely  increased  expense  to  set  up  separate  sets  of  books  for  tax 
purposes,  an  undesirable  result  in  itself.  The  present  law  permits  a  return  in 
accord  with  business  practice,  and  gives  the  Treasury  broad  powers  to  make  the 
necessary  rules  and  regulations  to  prevent  escape  from  the  tax.  In  the  judgment 
of  the  Departm.ent,  the  law  should  not  be  changed  in  this  particular. 33 

The  Treasur;^'s  spokesman  referred  to  the  fact  that  sometimes  State 
law  required  in  effect  multiple  incorporation  of  corporations,  as  in  the 

"  Sec.  141  (d).  Insurance  companies  were  excepted,  sec.  141  (e). 

29  Cong.  Rec,  75:  7124-7128. 

20  The  National  Industrial  Recovery  Act  of  1933  raised  the  differential  rate  to  1  percent.  The  regulations 
issued  under  the  1932  Revenue  Act  (series  78)  followed  substantially  the  previous  regulations  under  the 
1928  act  (series  75) .   ' 

31  Report  on  the  Revenue  Bill  of  1934,  p.  16. 

32  House  Ways  and  Means  Committee,  73d  Cong.,  2d  sess.,  Hearings  on  Revenue  Revision,  p.  85. 

33  Ibid.  In  the  absence  of  consolidated  returns,  the  tax  administrator  must  carefully  scrutinize  inter- 
corporate transactions  in  order  to  detect  the  creation  of  various  types  of  artificial  losses,  including  those 
resulting  from  intercompany  transfer  of  assets. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


45 


case  of  railroads.  Apparently  little  significance  was  attached  by  the 
Treasury  to  the  alleged  competitive  abuses  of  the  privilege.^* 

Obviously  influenced  by  the  stand  of  the  Treasury,  the  Ways  and 
Means  Committee  voted  to  override  the  report  of  its  subcommittee 
and  the  House  itself  voted  against  the  abolition  of  consolidated  tax 
returns.  In  the  Senate,  however,  the  objections  against  consolidated 
tax  returns  were  voiced  v\dth  greater  strength,  in  contrast  to  previous 
years  when  the  Senate  had  rejected  House  proposals  for  abolishing 
consolidated  returns. ^^  Instead  of  an  outright  abolition  of  the  privi- 
lege, however,  the  1934  Revenue  Act  permitted  consolidated  tax 
returns  to  be  filed  by  railroads,  in  consonance  with  the  practice  of 
the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  to  permit  consolidation  for 
regulatory  purposes.  The  consolidated  tax  returns  so  filed,  however, 
were  to  be  subject  to  an  additional  tax  of  2  percent  in  1934-35.  In 
1936  this  differential  tax  was  removed. 

The  resultant  change  took  the  form  of  a  new  definition  of  ''aflaiiated 
group,"  as  follows: 

*  *  *  an  "affiliated  group"  means  one  or  more  chains  of  corporations  con- 
nected through  stock  ownership  with  a  common  parent  corporation  if  *  *  * 
(provisions  (1)  and  (2)  as  in  the  1928  act)  (3)  each  of  the  corporations  is  either 
(A)  a  corporation  whose  principal  business  is  that  of  a  common  carrier  by  rail- 
road or  (B)  a  corporation  the  assets  of  which  consist  principall}'  of  stock  in  such 
corporations  and  which  does  not  itself  operate  a  business  other  than  that  of  a 
common  carrier  by  railroad     *     *     *.36 


All    other   corporations   must 
each  corporate  entity. 


file    separate  income-tax  returns   for 


IMPORTANCE    OF   CONSOLIDATED   RETURNS,    1928-33 

It  is  difficult  to  exaggerate  the  importance  of  consolidated  tax 
returns  in  the  operation  of  Federal  taxes  on  corporate  income  during 
the  period  1928-33.  Half  or  more  of  all  Federal  taxes  on  corporate 
income  were  reported  on  consolidated  tax  returns  in  the  years  1928-31. 
Half  or  more  of  the  total  taxable  income  reported  for  all  corporations 
came  from  consolidated  returns  for  the  years  1929-31,  while  the  gross 
income  reported  on  consolidated  returns  varied  from  44  to  48  percent 
of  the  gross  income  of  aU  corporations  for  the  same  period.  (See 
table  lY.) 


Table  IV. — Importance  of  consolidated  income-tax  retunu,  1928-33 
[Items  on  consolidated  tax  returns  as  percentages  of  items  on  all  returns] 


192S 

1929 

1930 

1931      1932 

1933 

Average 
1928-33 

Gross  income. ..  . 

45.6 
47.6 
49.9 

43.6 
51.1 
52.9 

47.6 
52.5 
55.9 

46.7 
50.1 
54.3 

39.6 
23.3 
23.5 

37.9 
27.9 
28.  6 

43.5 

Taxable  net  income 

42.1 

Federal  income  taxes 

44.2 

Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 


3^  See  the  exchange  of  remarks  between  Undersecretary  Magill  of  the  Treasury  and  Congressmen  Vinson 
and  McClint,  ibid,  pp.  104-05.  Cf.  a  contrary  statement  of  Robert  Jackson,  representing  the  Bureau  of 
Internal  Revenue,  during  the  1935  hearings  before  the  Senate  Finance  Committee,  pp.  223-226. 

3-^  See  Cong.  Rec,  78:5847,  6304-7,  6463-66.  6555-61. 

36  See  141  (d).  In  other  respects  the  Regulations  No.  89  issued  pursuant  to  the  1934  Revenue  Act  followed 
substantially  the  previous  regulations.  One  innovation  was  the  requirement  that  each  subsidiary  file  a 
special  form  consenting  to  the  use  of  the  consolidated  device  by  the  parent  member  of  the  affiliated  group. 
Art.  12.  The  1938  Revenue  Act  expanded  the  definition  to  include,  in  addition  to  the  foregoing,  "a  street 
or  suburban  trackless  trolley  system  of  transportation  operated  as  part  of  a  street  or  suburban  electric  rail- 
way or  trackless  trolley  system."  Sec.  141  (d)  (3).  The  1939  Revenue  Act  added  Pan-America  trading 
corporations  ito  the  {permissive  category.  The  second  Revenue  Act  of  1940  reintroduced  consolidated 
returns  for  purposes  of  the  new  excess-profits  tax. 


46  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

When  these  statistics  are  broken  down  in  terms  of  specific  industries 
(see  chart  XI),  it  is  apparent  that  consohdated  income-tax  returns 
played  an  overwhelming  role  in  public  utilities,  accounting  for  ap- 
proximately 80  percent  of  gross  income,  net  income,  and  Federal  taxes 
reported  for  that  industry  in  1929.  Next  in  order  of  importance  were 
manufacturing  and  mining,  where  consolidated  tax  returns  accounted 
for  approximately  60  percent  of  the  gross  income,  taxable  income, 
and  Federal  taxes,  respectively,  reported  in  1929.  Consolidated  tax 
returns  were  less  important  to  service  corporations  and  relatively 
unimportant  to  trade,  finance,  and  construction  corporations,  account- 
ing for  approximately  one-third  to  one-fifth  of  the  gross  income,  net 
income,  and  Federal  taxes,  respectively,  reported  in  1929. 

In  1933,  on  the  other  hand,  the  consolidated  tax  return  had  shrunk 
in  relative  importance.  The  decline  is  particularly  marked  in  the 
relative  importance  of  the  taxable  net  income  and  Federal  income 
taxes  reported  on  consolidated  income-tax  returns.  Substantial  de- 
clines, if  not  so  marked,  are  also  shown  in  the  relative  amount  of 
gross  income  reported  by  consolidated  corporations.  This  decline  in 
the  use  of  the  consolidated  returns  device  is  a  consequence  of  two 
factors — (a)  the  higher  tax  rates  applicable  to  consolidated  tax 
returns  (introduced  in  1932),  the  effect  of  which  is  primarily  reflected 
in  the  decline  in  relative  gross  income,  and  (b)  the  increasing  magni- 
tude of  intercompany  losses  during  the  course  of  the  depression. 

Within  manufactimng  there  are  also  marked  differences  in  the  im- 
portance of  the  consolidated  returns  (see  chart  XI).  Rubber,  chem- 
icals, metals,  food,  beverages,  and  tobacco  characteristically  made 
extensive  use  of  consolidated  tax  returns,  60  to  80  percent  of  the 
gross  income  of  which  was  reported  on  consolidated  tax  returns  in 
1929.  Consolidated  returns  were  relatively  unimportant  to  textiles, 
printing,  and  forest  products  corporations,  where  the  consolidated 
■group  accounted  for  only  20  to  30  percent  of  the  gross  income  reported 
for  those  industries  in  1929.  Leather,  paper,  and  stone,  clay,  and 
glass  occupied  a  middle  position  in  the  consolidated  tax-returns  picture, 
the  gross  income  reported  on  such  returns  accounting  for  approxi- 
mately 40  percent  of  that  shown  for  the  entire  industries  in  1929. 
Substantially  the  same  relationships  are  shown  for  taxable  net  income 
and  Federal  income  taxes  reported  on  consolidated  returns  in  1929. 

One  of  the  outstanding  facts  shown  in  chart  XI  is  that  in  1929  the 
bars  showing  the  percentile  importance  of  gross  income,  taxable  net 
income,  and  Federal  income  taxes  reported  on  consolidated  income 
tax  returns  tend  to  closely  parallel  one  another,  industry  by  industry 
(with  the  exception  of  rubber  and  chemicals).  This  substantial  coin- 
cidence means  that  given  amounts  of  gross  income  result  (after 
deductions  allowed  by  the  tax  laws)  in  similarly  proportioned  amounts 
of  taxable  net  income  upon  which,  in  turn,  similarly  proportioned 
amounts  of  Federal  corporate  income  taxes  that  are  reported  due 
and  payable. 

The  fact  that  these  three  percentages  for  consolidated  returns  of  all 
income  tax  returns  exhibited  a  fair  degree  of  constancy  can  be  taken 
to  prove  that  there  were  in  1929  no  marked  differences  between  con- 
solidated tax  returns  and  unconsolidated  tax  returns  in  the  determina- 
tion of  taxable  net  income  and  the  resultant  tax  liability  thereon.  In 
1933,  on  the  other  hand,  this  parallel  does  not  appear;  on  the  contrary 
the  relative  amounts  of  taxable  net  income  and  Federal  corporate 
income  taxes  of  the  consolidated  group  are  conspicuously  smaller  than 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


47 


the  relative  amount  of  gross  income,  industry  by  industry.  By  1933 
there  appeared,  then,  to  be  marked  differences  between  consolidated 
tax  returns  and  unconsolidated  tax  returns  as  to  the  determination  of 
taxable  net  income  and  the  resultant  tax  liability  thereon.  In  other 
words,  the  situation  with  respect  to  consolidated  income  tax  returns  in 
1933  represents  a  radical  change  from  what  the  situation  had  been  in 
1929. 

Chart  XI 

ROLE  OF  CONSOLIDATED  RETURNS  IN  FEOERAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAXATION,  I329  and  I933 
CONSOLIDATED  RETURNS  A8  i   OF  ALL  aETURNS 

1929  )933 

80^  60^  40^  20-^  0  20-r.  40?»  60^  Bo^ 


Manufacturing 

Mining 

Service 

Trade 

Construction 

Finance 

NET  raCOUE 

Public  UtUities 
Uanuf actur  ing 


SWTlO* 

Trade 


Codstruction 

FEDERAL  TAXES 

Public  Utilities 
HBDufacturlnc 


Serrlee 

Xr«d« 

Caostruotlon 


GBOSS  IHCOIIE 
Rubber 
Chemicals 
Uetals 

Food,  Beverages  &  Tobacco 
Laather 
Paper 

Stone,  Clay  &  Glass 
Printing 
Forest  products 
TextUee 


CheuiotLls 

Uetals 

Rubber 

Food,  Bererages  &  Tobacco 


Stons,  Clay  &  Glass 
Taxtilaa 

Printing 
Paper 

Forest  products 


Chemicals 

Hetals 

Rubber 

Food,  Beverages  4  Tobacco 

Leather 

Stone,   Clay  3c  Glass 

Printing 

Forest  products 

Paper 

TextUea 


Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 
Department  of  Commerce. 


48  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

DEDUCTION  OF  LOSSES  BY  SUBSIDIARIES 

The  differences  found  between  consolidated  and  unconsolidated 
income  tax  returns  may,  of  course,  be  the  reflection  of  many  factors, 
some  of  which  may  bear  no  relationship  to  the  device  of  consolidated 
tax  returns.  It  is  possible  to  eliminate  such  extraneous  factors  to 
some  extent  by  making  the  comparisons  industry-by-industry  rather 
than  for  corporations  as  a  whole.  The  nature  of  the  data  unfor- 
tunately does  not  permit  holding  the  size  factor  constant,  and  perhaps 
there  may  be  other  factors  whose  influence  cannot  be  fully  controlled. 
For  example,  the  gradual  tax  rate  penalization  of  corporations  filing 
consolidated  income  tax  returns  undoubtedly  led  some  of  the  corporate 
systems,  which  on  the  whole  were  profitable,  to  abandon  the  privilege 
and  to  file  separate  income  tax  returns  for  each  corporate  member  as  a 
unit  in  itself.  To  this  extent  only  corporate  systems  having  heavy 
losses  by  subsidiaries  that  would  outweigh  the  additional  tax  rate 
(three-fourths  of  1  percent  in  1932  and  1  percent  in  1933)  would  pre- 
sumably avail  themselves  of  the  privilege  of  filing  a  consolidated 
tax  return. 

In  other  words,  the  relative  financial  success  of  the  consolidated 
group  in  1932-33  was  probabty  lower  than  it  would  have  been  if  a 
discriminatory  tax  (however  slight)  had  not  been  imposed.  A  decline 
in  the  absolute  number  of  consolidated  tax  returns  did  occur,  changing 
from  8,495  in  1931  to  7,426  in  1932  and  to  7,101  in  1933,  a  decline 
of  16  percent.  But  the  absolute  number  of  unconsolidated  tax  returns 
also  declined,  falling  from  516,404  in  1931  to  508,636  in  1932  and  to 
504,080  in  1938,  a  decline  of  2.4  percent.  It  must  be  noted,  however, 
that  no  discriminatory  tax  was  imposed  in  1931  when  some  of  the 
trends  stresses  (infra)  had  already  begun,  that  after  a]l  the  statutory 
discrimination  was  relatively  minor  in  character  (at  most  1  percent), 
and  that  the  empirical  data  conform  to  the  main  hypothesis  derived 
from  a  reading  of  the  relevant  statutory  provisions.  The  statistical 
data  are  not  so  valid  as  could  be  desired,  but  their  deficiencies  are  not 
of  such  a  degree  as  to  preclude  realistic  analysis  or  conclusions.  In  no 
instance  do  the  data  fly  in  the  face  of  what  might  have  been  reasonably 
expected  from  an  a  priori  standpoint. 

Consolidated  and  unconsolidated  tax  returns  have  been  compared 
in  terms  of  the  amounts  of  taxable  net  income  and  total  gross  income 
reported  on  consolidated  tax  returns  as  percentages  of  the  respective 
items  reported  for  all  corporations.  The  broken  line  on  chart  XII 
shows  total  gross  income  reported  on  consolidated  tax  returns  in  the 
given  industr}^  as  percent  of  total  gross  income  reported  for  all  cor- 
porations in  the  same  industr}^  The  solid  line  shows  taxable  net 
income  reported  on  consolidated  tax  returns  (excluding  deficits)  in 
the  given  industry  as  percent  of  taxable  net  income  reported  for  all 
corporations  (excluding  deficits)  in  the  same  industry.  Whenever 
the  net  income  line  is  lower  than  the  gross  income  line,  it  is  assumed 
that  the  variation  between  the  two  lines  (show a  as  a  cross-hatched 
area)  shows  the  role  of  ofi'setting  losses  by  subsidiaries  in  the  opera- 
tion of  consolidated  income  tax  returns.  This  assumption  is  fortified 
by  the  fact  (a)  that  the  comparison  is  always  made  industry  by 
industry  and  (b)  that  the  larger  corporations  (among  which  naturally 
fell  the  consolidated  returns)  are  known  in  1931  to  1933  to  report 
relatively  larger  taxable  net  incomes  than  do  smaller  or  medium-sized 


^   — .  ^jCt 

£t 

s   g 

4 

m 

2  2  to 

^  o  y 

O  ^  cr 

o  ^  t- 

Q    U.    ^ 

uj   O  C> 

o  5  >- 
Zi  i^  °°      ^ 

is"  = 


I 

,M 

H 

V 

^ 

S 

i 

d 

-^  loj  ro 

g  CL  0> 

o  CO  2? 

UJ  CC  (/^ 

2  3  Z         o 

O  I-  a:      < 

O  LJ  =>          3 

2  cr  I-      i 

—  LlJ  < 

^  X  a:       5 
< 


% 

p 

o 

1- 

ff 

I 

\ 

z 
< 

z 

^ 

, 

P 

1 

1 

5^ 

I 

1 
1 

0*^1 

*^ 

■VWC 

*^^ 

^ 

« 

o     ° 


2    g      g      §     g     o 

^ 

\ 

J 

1 

?^ 

5? 

1 

^ 

> 

5 

1 

o     00 


pi 

o 


1 

^ 

5 

©gw 

o 

O  to  5 

■a  5 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


49 


I 


corporations .2^  Where  the  net  income  Hne,  on  the  other  hand,  is 
equal  to  or  greater  than  the  gross  income  hne  (the  variation  between 
which  is  a  striped  area),  no  clear  assumption  can  be  made,  for  sub- 
sidiary losses  may  still  remain  important  to  the  consolidated  group 
but  be  offset  by  the  relatively  larger  taxable  net  income  of  the  larger 
corporation  (which  probably  includes  the  major  part  of  the  consoli- 
dated group) . 

Froni  chart  XII  it  is  apparent  that  prior  to  the  coming  of  the 
depression  (1930-31)  consolidated  corporations  reported  the  same  or 
larger  taxable  net  incomes  in  relation  to  gross  income.  This  state- 
ment is  not  quite  applicable  to  finance,  public  utilities,  and  mining, 
nor  to  certain  manufacturing  industries  (i.  e.,  food,  beverages,  tobacco, 
rubber,  paper,  chemicals,  and  metals)  where  some  offsetting  losses  by 
subsidiaries  appear  to  have  occurred  in  1928  and  1929.^^ 

With  the  coming  of  the  depression,  however,  the  taxable  net  income 
reported  by  consolidated  companies  declined  relatively  much  more 
rapidly  than  the  taxable  net  income  reported  by  the  unconsolidated 
group.  This  decline  was  particularly  marked  in  manufacturing, 
mining,  and  public  utilities,  and  to  a  lesser  degree  in  finance,  service, 
and  construction.  No  decline  appeared  in  trade  where  the  taxable 
net  income  of  the  consolidated  group  remained  proportionately  larger 
than  its  gross  income. ^^  Within  manufacturmg  the  decline  w^as 
3specially  notable  in  food  (including  beverages  and  tobacco),  rubber, 
forest  products,  paper,  chemicals,  stone,  clay,  glass,  and  metals.  A 
iecline  occurred  in  the  remaining  manufacturing  industries  (i.  e., 
textiles,  leather,  and  printing),  but  was  distinctly  less  marked. 


ABOLITION    OF    CONSOLIDATED    TAX    RETURNS    IN    1934 

Further  light  on  this  problem  may  be  shed  by  statistical  examination 
)f  the  effects  of  the  statutory  abolition  in  1934  of  the  general  privilege 
)f  filing  consolidated  returns  upon  corporations  which  had  previously 
employed  such  consolidated  tax  returns.  Such  an  examination  can 
)e  made — albeit  only  in  an  approximate  manner  and  in  terms  of 
)road  industrial  groups  for  the  years  1933  and  1934 — by  virtue  of  a 

"  This  assertion  is  made  on  the  basis  of  the  following  table  computed  from  Statistics  of  Income: 
Taxable  net  income  {excluding  deficits)  as  percent  of  compiled  receipts  of  all  corporations 


Size  classes  (based  on  assets  in  thousands) 

1931 

1932 

1933 

Average 

Under  $50 

Percent 
1.5 
1.6 
2.0 
2.4 
2.6 
3.2 
4.4 
4.4 
4.3 

Percent 
0.7 
1.0 
1.3 
1.8 
2.2 
2.5 
3.4 
3.6 
3.6 

Percent 
0.9 
1.5 
2.1 
2.8 
3.5 
4.2 
4.8 
5.3 
4.0 

Percent 
1.0 

$50-$100 

.      1.4 

$100-$250 

1.8 

$250-$o00- .          . 

2.3 

$500-$1,000 

2.8 

$l,000-$5,000 

3.3 

$5,000-$10,000  .. 

4.2 

$10,000-$50,000 

4.4 

Over  $50,000 

4.0 

Note. — "Compiled  receipts"  differs  slightly  from  "gross  income"  by  including  interest  from 
governmental  securities,  but  this  discrepancy  from  the  basis  used  in  the  text  is  believed  to  be  very 
negligible. 

"  Data  on  consolidated  tax  returns  are  unfortunately  not  available  for  earlier  years.  Since  the  1928 
avenue  Act  imposed  several  limitations  upon  the  employment  of  consolidated  returns  (supra),  it  may  be 
njectured  that  previously  the  consolidated  tax  returns  device  may  have  been  more  extensively  used  than 
the  period  for  which  data  ai^  available. 

'°  This  industry  includes  chain  stores,  which  were  frequently  cited  in  connection  with  alleged  competitive 
uses  of  the  consolidated  returns  privilege. 


^Q  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMrC  POWER 

series  of  special  tabulations  of  identical  corporations  published  in 
Statistics  of  Income  for  1934.^°  The  central  point  of  this  comparison 
is  the  relationship  between  taxable  net  income  and  total  corporate 
receipts  for  the  consolidated  group  and  the  unconsolidated  group  of 
corporations  and  what  happened  to  this  relationship  in  1934  when 
the  privilege  of  filing  consohdated  tax  returns  was  repealed.  A  com- 
plicating factor  in  such  a  comparison  is  the  fact  that  1934  was  on  the 
average  a  better  year  than  1933  and  that  the  rate  of  recovery  may 
vary  with  industry  and  corporate  size.  This  factor  cannot  be  directly 
eliminated  from  the  comparison,  but  it  can  be  taken  into  account  to  a 
considerable  degree  by  noting  the  relative  change  of  the  two  groups 
of  corporations  in  given  industries.  It  must  also  be  recognized  that 
the  unscrambhng  of  consolidated  accounts  into  separate  accounts  for 
each  corporation  may  introduce  other  variables. 

The  method  involved  computing  taxable  net  income  as  percentages 
of  corporate  receipts  for  corporations  which  filed  consolidated  returns 
in  1933  and  which  filed  unconsolidated  returns  in  1934,  and  the  same 
percentages  for  corporations  which  were  unconsolidated  in  1933  and, 
of  course,  remain  unconsolidated  in  1934.  This  computation  makes 
it  possible  to  compare  the  increase  or  decrease  in  the  relative  amount  of 
net  income — that  is,  the  excess  of  corporate  receipts  over  allowable 
deductions  (including  losses  by  subsidiaries)  and  credits  for  investment 
income  "'^ — of  the  two  groups  of  corporations. 

The  results  of  this  comparison  are  shown  in  chart  XIII,  in  which 
are  plotted  the  1933-34  differences  between  the  percents  that  taxable 
net  income  was  of  compiled  receipts  for  the  2  years,  by  industries. 
If  the  line  goes  above  the  zero  line,  it  indicates  that  the  1934  per- 
centage was  larger  than  that  for  1933.  If  the  line  goes  under  the 
zero  line,  it  indicates  that  the  1934  percentage  decreased  from  that 
for  1933.  The  length  of  the  line  in  either  direction  indicates  the 
magnitude  of  the  change  between  the  2  years. 

When  this  comparison  is  made,  it  is  discovered  that  the  amount 
of  taxable  net  income  relative  to  corporate  receipts  remained  com- 
pletely unchanged  for  manufacturing  corporations  which  had  filed 
unconsolidated  returns  in  both  1933  and  1934.*^  On  the  other  hand, 
there  was  a  distinct  increase  in  the  amount  of  taxable  net  income 
relative  to  corporate  receipts  for  manufacturing  corporations  which 
had  filed  consolidated  tax  returns  in  1933  and  which  were  required  in 
1934  to  file  unconsolidated  tax  returns.  The  removal  of  the  privilege 
operated  to  increase  the  relative  taxable  net  income  of  manufacturing 
corporations.  This  same  tendency  for  the  consolidated  group  to 
increase  their  relative  taxable  net  income  while  the  unconsolidated 
group  remained  stationary  is  also  found  in  public  utilities. 

In  mining  both  the  consolidated  and  unconsolidated  group  of  cor- 
porations reported  relative  increases  in  taxable  net  income  from  1934 
over  1933,  but  the  increase  was  distinctly  larger  for  the  consolidated 
group    of    corporations    than   for   the   unconsolidated   group.     This 

«>  For  description  of  these  special  tabulations  and  statement  of  (lualifications  as  to  results,  see  Statistics 
of  Income  for  1934,  pt.  IT,  pp.  19-32. 

<i  The  net  loss  carry-over  provision  expired  in  1932  and  consequentlv  does  not  enter  into  any  comparison 
involving  1933  and  1934. 

«  For  simplicity  in  reference  the  phrase  "consolidated  groups"  shall  be  understood  to  mean  that  group- 
of  corporations  which  filed  consolidated  tax  returns  in  1933  and  were  later  unconsolidated  (except  for  rail- 
roads), while  the  phase  "unconsolidated  group"  shall  be  understood  to  mean  that  group  of  corporations, 
which  filed  unconsolidated  tax  returns  in  both  1933  and  1934. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


51 


tendency  was  also  characteristic  of  service,  finance,  and  trade.  A  third 
situation  is  found  in  certain  manufacturing  groups  (food  and  rubber) 
where  the  consolidated  group  of  corporations  reported  relative  in- 
creases in  taxable  income  in  1934  over  1933,  whereas  the  unconsoli- 
dated group  reported  relative  decreases.  A  fourth,  and  reverse, 
situation  is  found  in  tobacco  and  metals,  where  the  consolidated 
group  reported  relative  decreases  in  taxable  net  income  in  1934  over 
1933,  whereas  the  unconsolidated  group  reported  relative  increases. 

Chart  XIII 

EFFECT  OF  ABOLITION  OF  CONSOLIDATED  TAX  RETURNS  IN  1934ION  CORPORATE 
TAXABLE  NET  INCOME  BY  INDUSTRIES 


■n  C0RP0RATI0^4S  FOR  WHICH  CONSOLIDATED  RETURNS  WERE 

^"  riLEO  IN  f933 

m^  CORPORATIONS  FOR  WHICH  NO  CONSOLIDATED  RETURNS  WERE 

'^'^^  FILED  IN  1933 

{^^  ALL  CORPORATIONS 

><  NO  CHANGE 


Taxable  Net  Income  as  ^  of  Compiled  Receipts 

DECREASE  OF  1934  OVER  1933  INCREASE  OF  1934  OVER  1933 

43210123 


Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 
Department  of  Commerce, 


^2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

During  the  prosperity  years  (1928  and  1929 — the  earliest  years  for 
which  statistical  data  are  available)  the  consolidated  tax-returns  device 
did  not  appear  to  offer  substantial  tax  benefits  to  holding  companies 
and  related  forms  of  interafhliated  corporations.  The  reason  was 
fairly  simple:  During  that  period  there  were  not  substantial  losses  by 
subsidiaries  (except  in  a  few  industries,  e.  g.,  rubber)  that  could  be 
appropriately  deducted  via  consolidated  tax  returns  from  the  profits  of 
other  subsidiaries  or  of  the  parent.  With  the  coming  of  the  depres- 
sion, however,  and  the  intensification  of  the  downward  swing  of  the 
business  cycle  from  1930  to  1931  to  1932,  the  privilege  of  deducting 
subsidiary  losses  within  affiliated  systems  became  very  important  to 
the  member  corporations  of  the  system  in  reducing  their  tax  liability 
from  what  it  would  have  been  if  the  tax  laws  had  treated  each  corpo- 
ration as  a  unit  in  itself. 

Given  effective  administration  of  the  tax  laws,  the  filing  of  consoli- 
dated tax  returns  by  affiliated  corporations  results  at  best  in  the  same 
amount  of  taxes  that  would  have  been  collected  if  each  corporation 
had  been  taxed  separately.  In  any  depression  period  consolidated 
tax  returns  drastically  curtail  taxes  from  what  they  would  have  been 
on  an  unconsolidated  basis.  In  no  event  can  consolidated  tax  returns 
result  in  higher  tax  liability  than  that  computed  on  an  unconsoHdated 
basis,  provided  the  tax  laws  are  efficiently  enforced. 

It  may  be  argued  by  the  proponents  of  consolidated  tax  returns 
that  such  a  basis  for  computing  Federal  income  tax  liability  is  (a)  juster 
than  the  original  (before  1917)  and  present  (since  1934)  method  of 
determining  the  tax  liability  of  interaffiliated  corporations  and  (b)  is 
administratively  more  feasible,  for  the  reporting  taxpayer  and  the 
tax  collector.  The  argument  of  tax  justice  is  predicated  upon  the 
general  maxim  that  the  taxpaying  units  should  approximate  the  real 
business  units,  a  proposition  from  which  it  is  difficult  to  dissent  in  the 
abstract.  By  taxing  interaffiliated  corporations  on  a  consolidated 
basis,  it  may  be  argued,  the  tax  laws  are  but  treating  loosely  knit 
combinations  in  the  same  way  as  the  tax  laws  apply  to  merged  or 
consolidated  corporations.  The  one  consists  of  parents  and  sub- 
sidiaries while  the  other  consists  of  operating  departments  within  the 
framework  of  a  single  corporation.  Departmental  losses  in  the  latter 
case  are,  of  course,  offset  against  the  profits  of  other  departments  within 
the  same  corporation,  and  only  the  residual  is  subject  to  Federal  tax. 

This  argument  overlooks,  however,  a  very  important  point,  namely, 
that  loosely  knit  combinations  and  merged  or  consolidated  corpora- 
tions are  quite  different  in  nature,  each  from  the  other.  These 
differences  are  practically  identical  with  the  unique  advantages  of 
the  holding-company  teclmique  of  corporate  growth  which  were  set 
forth  at  the  beginning  of  this  chapter.  A  single  phrase  may  perhaps 
sum  up  these  differences — a  common  unit  of  responsibility,  or  the 
lack  of  such  a  unit.  The  merged  or  large  corporation  affords  such  a 
common  unit  of  responsibility.  The  holding  company  and  its  sub- 
sidiaries do  not  constitute  any  common  unit  of  responsibility.  In  the 
realm  of  contracts  and  torts,  employees  and  customers,  investors  and 
the  general  public,  corporations  are  usually  allowed  to  define  their 
duties  and  liabilities  strictly  in  terms  of  separate  corporate  entities, 
largely  irrespective  of  intercorporate  relationships.  By  defining  the 
''real  business  unit"  on  a  consolidated  basis  for  affiliated  companies, 
the  Federal  tax  laws  accepted  a  unit  of  responsibility  which  was  prac- 
tically nonexistent  elsewhere  in  corporate  relationships. 


CHAPTER  IV 

INTERCORPORATE  DIVIDENDS  AND  INTEREST  ON 
GOVERNMENTAL  SECURITIES 

Another  case  in  which  the  Federal  revenue  acts  have  clone  httle  to 
hinder  the  growth  and  continued  existence  of  vast  intercorporate  net- 
works is  the  treatment  accorded  dividend  income  in  Federal  corporate 
income  taxation.  It  is,  of  course,  obvious  that  the  privilege  of  filing 
a  consolidated  income-tax  return  involves  a  complete  disregard  of  all 
dividends  received  from  subsidiaries  within  the  affiliated  system,  but 
that  was  only  one  of  the  minor  aspects  of  the  consolidated  tax  returns 
device,  since  intercorporate  dividends  were  free  of  taxation  in  the 
hands  of  the  receiving  corporation  during  the  substantive  life  of  the 
consolidated  tax  returns  privilege. 

FEDERAL    TAXATION    OF    INTERCORPORATE    DIVIDENDS HISTORY 

The  Federal  corporate  excise  tax  of  1909  expressly  excluded  from 
corporate  income,  for  tax  purposes,  all  ''amounts  received  by  it  as 
dividends  upon  stock  of  other  corporations,  joint  stock  companies  or 
associations,  or  insurance  companies,  subject  to  the  tax  hereby 
imposed."  The  case  for  exempting  corporate  profits  derived  from 
dividends  was  stated  in  the  House  of  Representatives,  as  follows: 

Mr.  EscH.  As  the  corporation  tax  went  to  the  Senate  it  exchided  holding 
companies,  as  I  understand  it? 

Mr.  Payne  (who  had  previously  stated,  "I  have  no  use  for  an  income  tax"). 
It  certainly  does. 

Mr.  EscH.  What  is  the  reason  for  the  exclusion? 

Mr.  Payne.  There  is  no  reason  in  the  world  why  a  corporation  that  owns  stock 
in  another  corporation  should  pay  a  double  tax  upon  those  holdings.^ 

The  case  against  the  exemption  was  developed  at  considerable 
length  in  the  upper  legislative  branch  by  Senator  Newlands.  At  the 
outset  of  his  remarks  he  observed  that  the  problem  had  better  be 
analj^zed  in  terms  of  the  role  of  dividends  and  the  effect  of  their 
taxation  upon  different  types  of  corporation: 

Mr.  President,  there  are  three  kinds  of  holding  companies.  One  is  represented 
by  insurance  companies,  another  by  holding  railroad  companies,  another  by  the 
great  combinations  which  hold  the  stock  of  other  companies  for  the  purpose  of 
monopolizing  production. 

It  is  very  clear,  so  far  as  the  first  class  of  corporations  is  concerned,  such  as 
insurance  companies,  that  it  would  be  unjust  to  prevent  such  companies  from 
exempting  from  their  incom.e  the  dividends  received  from  corporations  which  pay 
this  tax,  for  insurance  companies  are  organized  for  the  purpose  of  investing  the 
money  of  their  policyholders  in  the  stocks  of  other  corporations,  and  such  invest- 
ment is  a  perfectly  legitimate  one  and  is  sanctioned  by  law. 

As  to  railroad  holding  corporations,  that  is  a  device  which  has  grown  up  from 
the  fact  that  the  United  States  has  never  as  yet  passed  a  national  corporation  law 
for  the  incorporation  of  interstate  railroads;  and  of  course  it  is  necessary  that  in 
some  way  the  union  of  railroads  organized  in  different  States,  but  when  joined, 

1  Cong.  Rec,  44:  4696. 

53 
262698— 4 l—No.  9 5 


^4  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

forming  continuous  lines,  should  be  accomplished  in  order  that  the  great  systems,, 
extending  from  ocean  to  ocean  and  through  many  States,  may  be  organized  in  such 
a  wav  as  to  meet  the  convenience  of  the  public. 

Therefore  certain  States  grant  charters,  enabhng  such  corporations  to  hold  the 
stocks  of  other  railroad  corporations  and  to  operate  the  roads  owned  by  various 
railroad  corporations  as  an  entire  system.  That  form  of  holding  corporation, 
though  it  is  a  clumsy  substitute  for  a  national  corporation  and  has  led  to  many 
evils  in  overcapitalization  and  escape  from  proper  control,  meets  the  convenience 
of  the  public;  and  as  the  various  constituent  corporations  under  it  are  subject  to 
public  regulation  and  control  as  natural  monopolies,  and  the  holding  company 
itself,  if  it  operates  the  continuous  line,  is  also  subject  to  public  regulation  and 
control,  no  m.oral  objection  can  be  made  to  that  form  of  a  holding  company.  ^  It 
would  be  unjust  as  to  that  form  of  a  holding  company  to  compel  it  to  pey  another 
tax  upon  the  income  received  from  the  dividends  of  corporations  which  have 
already  paid  this  tax. 

We  now  come  to  the  monopolistic  holding  com.pany,  the  great  trust  organized 
like  the  Steel  Trust,  for  the  purpose  of  holding  the  stock  of  other  constituent 
companies,  with  a  view  to  controlling  and  monopolizing  prodjiction  in  certain 
lines.  Such  an  organization  is  not  sustained  by  any  moral  consideration  and  is 
against  public  policy  and  the  spirit  of  the  interstate  commerce  law. 

The  objection  made  to  taxing  such  a  company  is  that  you  give  sa  nction  to  it, 
or,  at  all  events,  recognize  it  as  a  legalized  form  of  combination.  You  may 
not  sanction  it;  but  you,  by  the  law,  recogiiize  its  existence.  You  recognize  that 
existence  without  reprobation.  Such  an  organization  has  a  privilege  of  vast 
value,  if  it  is  to  be  regarded  as  legal;  for,  whilst  it  has  no  property  except  the  stock 
of  other  corporations  and  no  income  except  that  whicli  it  derives  from  other 
corporations  which  may  pay  the  tax,  yet  the  privilege  of  combination  itself  is 
one  of  vast  value.  You  cannot  reconcile  the  exemption  of  such  a  corporation  from 
a  direct  excise  tax  upon  that  vast  privilege  under  this  proposed  law. 

Therefore,  it  seems  to  me,  the  only  way  to  do  is  to  support  the  amendment  of 
the  Senator  from  Minnesota,  to  withdraw  this  particular  exemption  of  income  from 
the  bill,  and  afterward  to  shape  the  bill  in  such  a  Way  as  to  perniit  the  exemption 
of  the  income  derived  from  stocks  owned  by  insurance  companies  or  savings  banks 
organized  for  profit;  to  perm.it  the  exemption  of  the  income  derived  by  these 
great  holding  railroad  corporations  from  the  dividends  of  other  corporations 
subsidiary  to  it,  and  then,  if  we  propose  to  recognize  also  the  only  form  of  holding 
companies  that  is  subject  to  criticism — the  holding  corporations  organiz;ed  for 
monopolistic  purposes — we  should  frame  a  tax  especially  designed  to  reach  the 
value  of  the  great  privilege  which  they  en  joy. 2 

The  income-tax  law  of  1913,  however,  defined  net  income  very 
broadly  and  provided  for  no  special  treatment  of  intercorporate  divi- 
dends/ which  consequently  remained  fully  taxable  to  the  receiving 
corporation  from  March  1,^  1913,  onward.  In  the  course  of  the  House 
debate  on  the  1916  act,  Representative  Cordell  Hull  declared— 

The  dividends  received  by  one  corporation  from  the  stock  of  another  corporation 
are  not  exempted  from  the  tax.  This  provision  was  based  upon  the  policy  that  if 
a  corporation  desires  to  hold  stock  in  another  corporation,  with  all  the  corporate 
and  business  advantages  arising  therefrom,  it  should  not  object  to  paying  taxes 
accordingly  .3 

So  remained  the  state  of  the  law  till  the  War  Incom.e  Tax  Act  of  1917 
which  introduced  a  special  credit  from  corporate  gross  income  for  ''the 
amount  received  as  dividends  upon  the  stock  or  from  the  net  earnings 
of  anv  other  corporation  *  *  *  v/hich  is  taxable  upon  its  net 
income."  ""  Observe,  however,  that  the  ordinary  corporate  income 
tax  at  2  percent  remained  applicable  to  intercorporate  dividends 
throughout  1917— see  section  10  (a)  of  the  Income  Tax  Act  of  1916  as 
amended  in  1917 — and  that  an  attempt  in  Congress  to  enact  a  general 

2  Cong.  Rec,  44:  4232-423.3. 

3  Ibid.,  53;  509. 

*  Sec.  4  of  the  War  Income  Tax  Act  of  1917. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  55 

credit  for  intercorporate  dividends  was  defeated,  for  reasons  that 
clearly  appear  from  the  following  exchange  of  remarks: 

Mr.  KiTCHiNs.  Is  it  not  a  fact  that  practically  all  the  so-called  holding  com- 
panies of  the  corporations  are  organized  for  the  purpose  of  getting  all  the  sub- 
sidiary competing  companies  into  a  monopoly? 

Mr.  Lenroot.  Absolutely;  and  that  is  their  very  purpose,  and  this  amendment 
would  be  putting  a  premium  on  that  kind  of  corporation. ^ 

The  war  excess-profits  tax  of  1917  completely  exempted  intercor- 
porate dividends  received  from  corporations  already  subject  to  income 
tax.  The  1918  Revenue  Act  made  the  exemption  for  intercorporate 
dividends  complete  b}^  providing  that  they  were  deductible  whenever 
received  from  corporations  alread}^  taxed  thereon.  From  1918  to 
1934  intercorporate  dividends  received  from  domestic  corporations  and 
foreign  corporations  (more  than  half  the  gross  income  of  v/hich  was 
derived  within  the  United  States),  were  either  deducted  from  or  cred- 
ited against  corporate  gross  income.  In  1934  the  credit  was  limited 
to  dividends  received  from  domestic  corporations  subject  to  Federal 
income  taxation.®  Corporations  could  no  longer  deduct  dividends 
received  from  dom.estic  corporations  exempt  from  Federal  income 
taxation  or  received  from  foreign  corporations.  The  1935  Revenue 
Act  hmited  the  deduction  to  90  percent  of  such  intercorporate  divi- 
dends, and  this  limitation  was  increased  to  85  percent  by  the  Revenue 
Act  of  1936,  which  provision  is  presently  (September  1940)  in  effect. 
The  1936  act  introduced  a  novel  provision  with  respect  to  mutual 
investment  trusts,  which  were  authorized  to  claim  full  credit  for  all 
dividends  paid  out  but  no  credit  for  dividends  received. 

Under  the  excess-profits  tax  enacted  by  the  second  Revenue  Act 
of  1940  all  intercorporate  dividends  (whether  derived  from  domestic 
or  foreign  corporations)  were  excluded  from  base  of  income  from 
which  ^'excess  profits"  are  to  be  computed. 

To  sum^marize  the  taxability  of  intercorporate  dividends  in  the 
hands  of  the  receiving  corporation:  Prior  to  March  1913  and  from 
1918  through  1935  such  dividends  were  not  included  in  the  taxable 
net  income  of  corporations.  From  March  1913  through  1917  they 
were  fully  taxable  under  the  ordinary  corporate-income  tax.  In  1917 
they  were  excluded  from  the  corporate  income  subject  to  the  war- 
income  tax  of  4  percent  and  the  excess-profits  tax  (at  graduated 
rates). ^  Since  1936,  15  percent  of  intercorporate  dividends  have  been 
subject  to  the  Federal  normal  corporation-income  tax.^ 

The  avoidance  of  double  taxation  furnishes  the  basis  for  exempting 
from  Federal  taxation  all  or  the  major  part  of  intercorporate  dividends. 
According  to  this  argument,  the  corporate  profits  out  of  which  divi- 
dends are  distributed  had  been  previously  taxed  in  the  hands  of  the 
distributing  corporation  and  to  tax  the  dividends  when  received  is  to 

5  Cong.  Rec,  55:  92494. 

6  Sec.  23  (p).  In  the  ensuing  debate  on  this  modification  Senator  Borah  argued  for  the  complete  elimina- 
tion of  the  deduction  of  intercorporate  dividends.    See  Cong.  Rec,  78:  6467. 

7  The  tax  treatment  of  intercorporate  dividends  during  this  interim  (1913-17)  is  somewhat  complicated 
by  the  fact  that  under  the  1917  act  the  rate  of  the  tax  on  dividends  varied  with  the  rate  prevailing  during 
the  period  when  the  dividends  were  presumably  earned  by  the  distributing  corporation.  Thus  dividends 
received  in  1917  were  taxed  at  (a)  1  percent  when  paid  out  of  earnings  of  1913-1-3  and  (b)  2  percent  when 
paid  out  of  earnings  of  1916-17. 

8  During  the  life  of  the  surtax  on  undistributed  profits  (1936-38),  discussed  in  the  following  chapter, 
intercorporate  dividends  were  fully  included  in  taxable  net  income,  against  which,  of  course,  the  corpora- 
tion was  entitled  a  special  credit  for  all  taxable  dividends  distributed. 


56  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

tax  the  same  income  twice.  It  is  obvious  that  the  case  is  not  of  100- 
percent  double  taxation,  for  the  amount  distributed,  according  to  the 
argument,  must  already  have  been  reduced  pro  rata  by  the  amount 
of  the  tax  paid  thereon  by  the  distributing  corporation.^  It  is  also 
obvious  that  the  taxation  of  intercorporate  dividends  involves  no 
double  taxation  in  any  constitutional  sense  since  the  taxable  units 
are  different  corporate  entities. 

But  the  argument  of  double  taxation  may  have  little  to  do  with 
the  taxation  of  intercorporate  dividend  as  a  matter  of  national  eco- 
nomic policy.  Intercorporate  affiliation  is  the  consequence  of  the 
exercise  of  a  higbJy  valuable  privilege — the  right  of  one  corporation 
to  own  stock  in  another  corporation  with  incidental  control  and  result- 
ing profits — with  which  corporations  have  been  endowed  by  State 
law.     And  such  a  legal  privilege  may  be  appropriately  taxed. 

MAGNITUDE   OF  THE  TAX   CREDIT  FOR   INTERCORPORATE   DIVIDENDS   FOR 
CORPORATIONS   OF  VARYING  INDUSTRIES,  1926-37 

The  importance  of  the  special  tax  credit  for  intercorporate  divi- 
dends for  various  industries  in  the  years  1926  to  1937  is  shown  graph- 
ically in  chart  XIV.  The  lowest  line  of  each  industry  graph  shows 
the  ratio  of  Federal  tax  to  total  corporate  profits,  disregarding  the 
taxable  character  of  specific  sources  of  corporate  profits  (i.  e..  Govern- 
ment interest)  and  looking  at  each  corporation  as  a  separate  entity — 
as  they  are  in  law,  generally.  The  second  layer  shows  the  ratio  of 
taxes  to  corporate  profits  less  the  credit  for  intercorporate  dividends 
(100  percent  in  1931-35  and  85  percent  in  1936-37).  The  area  be- 
tween the  first  and  second  ratio  shows  the  extent  to  which  the  Federal 
revenue  acts  have  dealt  with  intercorporate  affiliation  by  totally  or 
partially  exempting  the  income  resulting  from  such  relationships  (i.  e., 
intercorporate  dividends)  from  taxation  in  the  hands  of  the  recipient 
corporations.  If  such  dividends  income  had  not  been  exempted  from 
or  credited  against  net  income  on  the  rationale  of  ''double  taxation," 
corporate  taxes  would,  in  fact,  have  been  higher  by  the  amount  of 
the  cross-hatched  area.  It  is  the  scope  of  this  credit  which  is  of 
particular  importance  in  the  present  section. 

Before  examining  the  industrial  and  size  characteristics  of  this 
credit,  it  would  probably  be  in  the  interest  of  clarity  to  complete  the 
description  of  the  chart,  although  the  other  layers  are  of  interest  only 
in  the  succeeding  sections  of  this  chapter.  The  third  ratio  shows 
taxes  as  percent  of  corporate  profits  less  the  credit  for  intercorporate 
dividends  and  less  the  amount  of  interest  received  on  governmental 
securities. ^^  The  fourth  line  (found  only  for  1932  and  prior  years) 
shows  the  ratio  of  taxes  to  corporate  profits  less  the  credits  for  invest- 
ment income  and  the  deduction  of  prior  years'  losses;  the  variation 
between  the  third  and  fourth  lines  shows  the  relative  importance  of 
the  prior  years'  loss  deduction.     For  the  years  1926-32,  inclusive,  the 

'  It  is  also  apparent  that  the  double-taxation  argument  assumes  that  the  Federal  taxes  paid  by  the  dis- 
tributing corporation  equally  or  proportionally  affect  the  profits  that  are  distributed  as  dividend,  and  the 
profits  that  are  reinvested  in  or  by  the  earning  corporation.  Only  the  latter  may  be  visibly  affecteds  at 
least  in  the  short  run,  if  the  dividends  distributed  continue  in  the  same  or  greater  volume.  Unless  divi- 
dends are  actually  diminished  by  income  taxes  paid  by  the  distributing  corporation,  it  is  difTicult  to  regard 
the  same  as  falling  on  the  corporate  stockholder  until  the  final  day  of  reckoning  (which  may  be  indefinitely 
postponed). 

10  Since  1936  the  third  ratio  also  excludes  from  the  denominator  the  amount  of  the  excess-profiis  tax,  which 
Is  usually  very  slight  in  dollars  (except  in  the  smaller  size  classes).    See  infra,  pp.  60-70. 


t 

5  

i , 

z 

-1- 

-i 

-i 

n 

' — 

■ — ■ 

'- — ' 

-^ 

n 

^    ! 

^ 

1 

i 

ffl^ 

1 

— 

#j 

— 

— 

i 
-1 

a 

p 

i 

-y 

-i 

i 

1 

1 

! 

• 

i 

i 

i 

i 

i 

^M| 

N 

1 

!2      Z 

i 

1 

-i 

! 

% 

M 

— 1 

-i 
-I 

1 

— 

1 1 

1 

3  - 

! 

— 

1 

J 

I  ^ 

i 

ft  ^ 

1 

i     _ 

° 

f 

9 

i      1 

^ipr" 

ifx 

>^ 



-i 

— 

^  -- 

5 

Ul 

i 

^- 

^ 

_l_ 

i 

^^ 

i 

i 

i 

i 

i 
&  — 

i 

s 

6      < 

s 

''i 

1 

"^ 

!  1  !i 

1 

»• 

•^ 

S* 

\ 

1 

s 

1 

W^ 

\ 

s 

z 

i 

Bi    s 

o 

t- 

i 

1 

T^v  'i 

~ 

i^X%5 

)1 

^    1 

i 

s 

1  i'li 

i 

SI 

■    ^ 

1 

I 

iJr-i 

fr 

-^      71/      '        ■ 

~ 

lilt 

•lis 


Z 
<  in 


1 

w 

i 

- 

s 

-O- 

o 

-1 
1 

-1 

i 

^\ 

1 

- 

/ 

i 

, 

/ 

i 

s 

rPs 

2 

2 

i 

fi 

1 

1 

» 

i 

M 

"^1 

? 

i 

4 

111 

k 

\ 

\ 

i 

= 

Si 

^ 

i 

" 

i 

o 
in- 

-i 
J 

P 

i 

" 

1 

-| 

^ 

a 

/ 

J 

% 

1 

X 

1 

i 

1 

4 

1 

r, 

II 

s 

^ 

!>>' 

1 

: 

a: 

1- 

M 

-i 

*s. 

s 

: 

s 

1 

= 

i 

: 

5 

- 

: 

i 

1 

1 

g 

1^ 

1 

i 

1 

^^^ 

^ 

i| 

g 

I 

i 

i 

1 

s. 

i 

4 

1 

i 

-B- 

F^ 

i 

^ 

r 

Tl 

i 

JL  1 

8 

K^-^  1- 

— 

i  ^W     '  1 

i    f     '  i 

Z  i      ^^Sfe,  i 

S  fi      r\  \y 

Si"      -     \  /  \  i 

i     \f  /  ? 

!       I    J ./    I 

l/fy     I 

i       lfe^%5w 

1 

i. 

i 

J"**^^   s 

1      1      '      P 

1  '^@    1 

!   1   1: 

M\ 

1  i  i: 

1    1       I: 

I 

= 

— 

i 

ig 

I     i: 

1 

i 

H 

I 

\M 

1 

W 

1 

J 

_ 

il 

_ 

_ 

i 

1 1 

I   I 
if  i 
s^i  i 

^a  a  - 
ft"  I 

ilil 


(\> 


\i 


-^ 

K)  > 

-  ^  ro 
§  ^  =j 
^    — I  s 

g    CO   LJ 

Ut  2h,       jQ 

XI     — 
X     -<    X 

>  m  > 


8-^ 


# 


O 
:s3 


> 

o 

O 


> 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POAVER  57 

fourth  line  gives  the  effective  tax  rate  (i.  e.,  taxes  as  percent  of  legal 
income),  while  this  rate  is  given  by  the  third  line  for  the  years  1933-37. 

It  is  readily  apparent  from  the  chart  that  the  tax  credits  vary  con- 
siderably from  industry  to  industry  and  also  from  year  to  year  in 
any  given  industry.  The  increase  in  importance  of  these  tax  credits 
to  an  industry  reflects  the  diminishing  importance  of  operating  income 
to  that  industry  and  the  increasing  importance  of  intercorporate 
affiliation  and  investments  in  governmental  securities,  as  in  finance, 
public  utilities,  mining,  and  such  manufacturing  industries  as  rubber 
and  chemicals.  There  is  no  necessity  for  reciting  at  length  in  the  text 
what  is  apparent  from  inspection  of  the  charts. 

The  size  characteristics  of  the  intercorporate  dividends  credit  are 
shown  in  chart  XV  for  the  years  1931-37."  Each  year  is  sho^\Ti  as  a 
pyramid  consisting  of  9  sectors  (1931-35)  or  10  sectors  (1936-37), 
each  representing  1  size  class  (identified  by  numbers  1  to  10),  with 
the  smaller  corporations  on  the  left,  the  larger  corporations  on  the 
right,  and  the  medium-sized  corporations  in  between.  Otherwise 
the  construction  of  the  chart  closely  parallels  that  of  chart  XIV  which 
has  been  described  in  detail  in  the  foregoing  paragraphs. 

An  examination  of  chart  XV  shows  that  the  size  patterns  of  the 
corporate  normal  income  tax  falls  into  four  district  periods: 

(1)  1931,  when  the  effective  tax  rate  (i.  e.,  after  all  credits  for  invest- 
ment income)  w^as  steeply  progressive — that  is,  the  magnitude  of  the 
rate  varied  directly  with  corporate  size.  The  explanation  of  this 
progressive  pattern  is  to  be  found  primarily  in  the  special  exemption 
of  a  minimum  amount  of  net  income  ($3,000)  available  to  corporations 
w4th  net  income  under  $25,000.^^ 

(2)  1932,  when  the  effective  tax  rate  (after  all  credits  for  investment 
income)  was  relatively  flat  or  very  slightly  progressive.  The  slightly 
progressive  shape  of  this  pyramid  may  be  attributed  to  the  special 
deduction  available  to  corporations  with  fluctuating  income  (usually 
smaller  corporations),  which  were  permitted  to  deduct  prior  years' 
operating  losses. ^^ 

(3)  1933-35,  when  the  size  pattern  of  effective  rates  (after  all  credits 
for  investment  income)  was  relatively  flat.  The  chart  clearly  shows, 
especially  in  the  case  of  the  large  corporation,  the  growing  importance 
of  the  credit  for  intercorporate  dividends. ^^ 

(4)  1936-37,  when  the  effective  rate  of  the  normal  tax  (after  all 
credits  for  investment  income)  was  again  somewhat  progressive — 
although,  it  should  be  noted,  not  at  all  to  the  extent  of  the  1931  pattern. 
The  change  in  the  revenue  acts  between  1936-37  and  the  revenue  acts 
applicable  to  1934-35  was  to  lower  the  normal  tax  on  the  smaller 
corporations,  particularly  with  assets  under  $100,000  and  to  leave 
substantially  unchanged  the  effective  tax  rates  for  the  medium-sized 
and  larger  corporations. 

It  is  obvious  from  an  inspection  of  the  chart  that,  aside  from  the 
slight  progression  in  the  statutory  rates  of  the  normal  tax,  the  major 
factors  contributing  to  the  size  shape  of  1936-37  tax  pyramids  was  the 
credit  for  85  percent  of  intercorporate  dividends.     The  magnitude  of 

11  No  size  data  are  available  for  earlier  years. 

12  Supra,  pp.  23-24. 

13  This  factor  has  been  discussed  at  length  in  the  previous  chapter  (supra,  pp.  36-38)  and  is  not  of  further 
concern  here. 

1*  The  1931  abolition  of  the  consolidated  tax  returns  privilege,  in  which  intercorporate  transactions  were 
eliminated,  contributed  in  part  to  the  statistical  increase  of  intercorporate  dividends. 


58 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XV 


FEDERAL  (NORfML)  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAX  PAYf^ENTS  AS  PERCENT  OF  PROFITS 
OF  CORPOP-VnONS  OF  VARYING  SIZE,    1531-37 

(RETURNS  WITH  NET  INCOivIE  ONLY) 


LEGENO 


ASSET    SIZE    CLASSES 

(  UNDER     ^50,000 

2  *50,000   TC  ^100.000 

3  100,000  TO  250,000 

4  250.000  TO  500  000 

5  500.000  TO  i. 000.000 

6  1,000,000  TO   5.000.000 

7  5,000  000   TO   10.000.000 

8  10,000,000  TO   50,000,000 

9  50,000,000  TO  100.000.000 

10  OVER   100.000  000 


^^  TAX  AS  ^  OF  COMPILED  NET  PROFITS 

R;3331  TAX  AS  ^  OF  COMPILED  NET  PROFITS  LESS 

^^'^'^^  TAX  EXEWPT  DIVIDENDS  RECEIVED 

^^  TAX  AS  1!>  OF  COMPILED  NET  PROFITS  LESS 

^'^^^'^     TAX  EXEMPT  DIVIDENDS  RECEIVED  AND  LESS 
INTEREST  RECEIVED  ON  GOVERNMENT  OBLI- 
GATIONS 


FxTm  TAX  AS  ^  OF  COMPILED  NET  PROFITS  LESS 

TAX  EXEMPT  DIVIDENDS  RECEIVED  AND  LESS 

INTEREST  RECEIVED  ON  GOVERNMENT  OBLi- 
GATIONS  LESS  NET  LOSS  FOR  PRIOR  YEARS 

^mm   TAX  ON  INTERCORPORATE  DIVIDENDS  AS  ^  OF 
"^  COMPILED  NET  PROFITS 

SOURCE:  COMPUTED  FROM  STATISTICS  OF  INCOME  FOR  RESPECTIVE  YEARS 


/Z3*56763    /23456T69     /234S67Q9     /234S67e9     1^34567^3     /  Z3-tS67e%iO  IZ3456789of0 


1931  1932  1933 

DEPARTMENT  OF  COMf^ERCE 


1934  1935  1936  1937 


COXGENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  59 

this  special  credit  shows  a  distinct  tendency  to  vary  directly  with  cor- 
porate size — that  is,  the  larger  the  corporation  the  greater  the  credit 
claimed  for  intercorporate  dividends.  This  credit  is  not  quite  so  ex- 
tensive in  1936-37  as  it  was  in  prior  years  when  all  dividends  received 
from  domestic  corporations  subject  to  tax  were  credited  against  or 
deducted  from  net  incom.e  under  the  normal  tax. 

When  the  size  pyramid  for  1937  is  broken  down  by  industries,  the 
general  size  pattern  is  naturally  substantiated  with  a  few  interesting 
extremes.  See  chart  XVI.  In  a  few  industries  (construction,  to- 
bacco, textiles,  and  clothing)  the  credits  for  intercorporate  dividends 
and  for  Government  interest  were  relatively  unimportant,  even  in  the 
largest  size  classes.  In  the  case  of  such  major  industries,  however, 
as  manufacturing,  mining,  service,  and  finance,  it  is  obvious  that  the 
special  credit  for  intercorporate  clividends  played  a  very  major  role 
for  the  largest  corporations.  This  observation  is  also  applicable  to 
such  manufacturing  industries  as  food,  forest  products,  chemicals, 
petroleum,  stone-clay-glass,  mietals,  and  motor  vehicles,  while  the  credit 
for  intercorporate  dividends  was  relatively  unimportant  to  public 
utilities  (except  the  very  largest  size  class),  beverages  (except  the 
very  largest  size  class),  leather,  rubber,  paper  and  printing,  and,  as 
already  noted,  in  construction.  The  surprisingly  small  role  of  the 
intercorporate  dividend  credit  for  public  utilities  results  in  part  from 
the  fact  that  the  consolidated  returns  privilege  is  still  available  to  rail- 
roads and  related  common  carriers,  resulting  in  the  complete  elimina- 
tion of  intercorporate  transactions  (includmg  intercorporate  dividends). 

The  industrial  comparison  is  given  in  greater  detail  for  91  groups  in 
chart  XVII  (the  construction  of  which  is  substantially  similar  to  that 
of  charts  XV  and  XVI).  The  credit  for  intercorporate  dividends  is 
most  prominent  among  the  various  types  of  financial  corporations — 
insurance,  banks,  and  investment  trusts.  But  the  dividend  credit  was 
also  c[uite  important  to  a  number  of  nonfinancial  corporations — nota- 
bly electric  light  and  power,  motor  vehicles,  airplanes,  sugar,  steam 
railroads,  chemicals,  and  petroleum.  The  role  in  other  industries  is 
apparent  from  inspection  of  the  chart  and  therefore  need  not  be 
elaborated.  ^^ 

The  partial  taxation  of  intercorporate  dividends  under  the  Revenue 
Act  of  1936  and  subsequent  years  probably  has  operated  as  a  mild 
deterrent  to  holding  companies  and  related  forms  of  interafiiiiated 
corporations.  At  the  time  of  its  introduction  into  the  Revenue  Act 
of  1935  the  limited  taxation  of  dividends  was  conceived  primarilj^  as 
an  auxiliary  enforcement  device  of  the  graduated  rate  structure  which 
was  introduced  at  the  samic  time.  Without  a  tax  on  intercorporate 
dividends,  it  was  considered,  corporate  taxpayers  might  be  tempted 
to  evade  the  graduated  tax  rates  by  splitting  one  corporation  into 
several  corporate  entities  for  the  purpose  of  reducing  the  size  of  each 
corporation's  income.  To  this  extent  the  limited  taxation  of  inter- 
corporate dividends  is  probably  effective. 

The  ''mild"  character  of  the  deterring  effect  on  holding  companies  of 
the  present  method  of  taxing  intercorporate  clividends  can  be  easily 

15  The  influence  of  the  statutory  graduation  of  the  rate  structure  (of  the  1936  Revenue  Act)  in  specific 
industries  can  be  observed  by  comparing  the  effective  tax  rate  (i.  e.,  normal  tax  as  of  corporate  profits  after 
all  credits  for  dividends  and  governmental  interest).  In  pipe  lines,  office  equipment,  railroads  (steam  and 
electric),  light  and  power,  motor  vehicles— all  industries  that  are  characteristically  organized  on  large 
scale— the  effective  rates  of  the  normal  tax  are  relatively  high,  while  the  rates  are  relatively  low  for  con- 
struction and  service— both  industries  characteristically 'organized  as  small-scale  enterprises. 


60 


CONCENTPvATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XVI 


FEDERAL  NORMAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAX  PAYAAENTS 
AND  CREDITS  FOR  INVESTMENT  INCOME 

BY  SIZE  CLASSES  AND  MAJOR  INDUSTRIES,  1937 


23456789   10 
CONSTRUCTION 


Source:  Computed  from  the  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue. 
Department  of  Commerce. 

substantiated  by  an  examination  of  the  actual  tax  rates.  Only  15 
percent  of  intercorporate  dividends  is  at  present  subject  to  Federal 
taxation;  the  remaining-  85  percent  is  tax  exempt.  This  partial  tax- 
ation of  intercorporate  dividends  was  at  most  equivalent  (a)  in  1936-37 
to  a  tax  of  2.3  percent  of  all  dividends  received  from  domestic  corpo- 
rations, (6)  in  1938-39  to  a  tax  of  2.5  percent,  and  (c)  in  1940  to  a  tax 
of  3.6  percent.  The  partial  taxation  of  intercorporate  dividends  can 
be  measured  only  indirectly  and  somewliat  roughly  for  1937  (shown 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XVI — Continued 


61 


FEDERAL  NORMAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAX  PAYMENTS 
AND  CREDITS  FOR  INVESTMENT  INCOME 

BY  SIZE  CLASSES  AND  MANUFACTURING  INDUSTRIES  1937 


1 UNDER 

$  50.0C0 

2             ..50.000    TO 

3-      -.100 

000  ro 

250,000 

4_      ._250 

000    TO 

500.000 

5             _50C 

300   TO 

000    TO 

5.000,000 

7 5,00C 

000    TO 

10.000,000        1 

8         lO.OOC 

000    TO 

50.000,000 

9-     SO.OOC 

000    TO 

100,000.000 

100,000  000        1 

Source:  Computed  from  the  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue. 
Department  of  Commerce. 

as  cross  hatching  supeiimposed  on  the  area  representing  the  tax-profits 
ratio).  As  expected,  the  intercorporate  dividend  tax  was  substan- 
tially nonextant,  or  at  least  it  could  not  be  shown  graphically  in  the 
smallest  size  classes  (assets  under  $100,000)  and  it  increased  in  magni- 
tude directly  with  corporate  size. 


62 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XVI — Continued 


FEDERAL  NORMAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAX  PAYMENTS 
AND  CREDITS  FOR  INVESTMENT  INCOME 

BY  SIZE  CLASSES  AND  MANUFACTURING  INDUSTRIES  1937 


pili 


iiiBlil 


:        ASSET_S.LE_CLAS_S 

;  1 UNDER 

2 50,000  TO 

•  3 100,000  TO 

4 250,000  TO 

5 500.000  TO 

6 1,000,000  TO   5 

:  7 5,000,000  TO   10 

,  8__IO.OOO,000  TO  50 

;  9-J50,000,000  to  100 

.0 OVES     100 

E.S 

;  50,000   1 

100,000 
250,000 
500.000 
000.000 
000.000 
000,000 
000,000 
000,000 
000,000 

To.  oi  V.  of  Co'l 


iQl  Ton  OS  %Qi  Corpofole  Prodi 

Credits  for  Inlercorpofolc 
icr.as    85  % 


Ta«  ail.  of  Cori 


Source:  Computed  from  the  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue. 
Department  of  Commerce. 


m 


1°     teS 
°5      sS 

f5 

1 

gS      2fe 

Sw      SS 

}^ 

la  p 

5^^   g" 

8 

s  ii  os 

fe 

S 

1  o3j  2gS 

tf 

i 

11  0 

UULi 


-JIUJ 


yi&MUr' 


CONOENTKATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


63 


There  is  some  evidence  to  indicate  that  intercorporate  affiliations 
have  been  shghtly  declining  in  importance,  in  part  perhaps  as  a  con- 
sequence of  the  limited  taxation  of  intercorporate  dividends.  The 
data,  for  whatever  they  may  be  worth,  are  presented  in  the  following 
table: 

Table  V. — Magnitude  of  intercorporate  dividends,  1935-37 


1935 

1 
1936 

3,013 

2.63 

50.60 

2,677 

2.02 

36.30 

1,492 

1.92 

32.10 

2,504 
2.38 
34.90 

1937 


I.   DIVIDEND  EECEIVED   BY   ALL   CORPORATIONS 

Amount  (millions  of  dollars) .._ 3,013  2,677  2,682 

Percent  of  corporate  receipts 2.63  2.02  1. 

Percent  of  cash  dividends  paid  out... 50.60  36.30  35.70 

II.  DIVIDENDS  RECEIVED   BY  NET-INCOME  CORPORATIONS 

Amount  (millions  of  dollars) 1,492  2,504  2,515 

Percent  of  corporate  receipts---- 1.92  2.38  2.30 

Percent  of  cash  dividends  paid  out 32.10  34.90  34.40 

Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 

But  the  evidence  is  not  very  conclusive.  The  record  of  all  corpora- 
tions as  a  group,  including  the  profitable  and  the  unprofitable,  indicate 
between  1935  and  1937  a  drop  in  the  absolute  amount  and  in  the 
relative  magnitude  of  intercorporate  dividends.  If  only  the  net- 
income  corporations  are  considered,  there  is,  on  the  contrar}^,  a  sub- 
stantial increase  in  both  the  absolute  amounts  and  in  the  relative 
magnitude  of  intercorporate  dividends.  The  partial  taxation,  of 
intercorporate  dividends  may  have  played  a  role,  among  other 
factors, ^^  in  specific  instances  of  the  simplification  of  corporate  struc- 
tures that  have  recently  been  taking  place. ^^  The  effect  of  the  inter- 
corporate dividend  tax  has  on  the  whole  been  rather  negligible. 


CORPORATE    INVESTMENT    IN    GOVERNMENT    SECURITIES 

Corporations  have  been  acquiring  securities  issued  by  governmental 
units — Federal,  State,  and  local — and  have  successfully  claimed  an 
exemption  for  all  interest  derived  from  such  securities  during  most  of 
the  life  of  the  Federal  corporation  income  tax.  The  basis  for  this 
exemption  in  the  case  of  interest  received  from  State  and  local  obliga- 
tions rests  presumably  on  that  traditional  doctrine  of  American  con- 
stitutional law  which  forbade  the  members  of  a  Federal  system  from 
taxing  one  another.  This  basis  is  ' 'presumed"  only,  for  such  interest 
was  fully  taxed  under  the  corporation  excise  tax  of  1909,  with  the 
specific  approval  of  the  United  States  Supreme  Court  in  Flint  v. 
Stone  Tracy }^    But  the  general  income  tax  law  of  1913  exempted 

19  A  novel  provision  was  introduced  into  the  capital-gains  provision  of  the  1935  Revenue  Act  (sec.  110  (a)) 
for  the  purpose  of  facilitating  the  simplication  of  corporate  structures  by  exempting  from  tax  all  property 
received  by  one  corporation  on  the  complete  liquidation  of  another  corporation.  This  provision  that  the 
receipt  of  such  property  shall  not  result  in  a  taxable  capital  gain  has  been  limited  to  cases  where  the  receiving 
corporation  owned  80  percent  of  the  voting  stock  of  the  liquidating  corporation.  See  Internal  Revenue 
Laws,  sec.  112  (b)  (6),  and  Regulations  103,  sec.  19.112  (b)  (6)-l-5. 

Under  the  1938  Revenue  Act  (sec.  371)  it  is  expressly  stipulated  that  no  recognition  as  to  gain  or  loss  shall 
be  given  to  exchanges  of  stocks  or  securities  "in  obedience  to  an  order  of  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Com- 
mission." 

1'  Facing  the  Tax  Problem  (at  p.  547)  cites  a  few  specific  corporate  systems  which  allegedly  abandoned 
subsidiaries  because  of  the  taxation  of  dividends. 

18  220  U.  S.  107  (1911):  "Vv^here  a  tax  is  lawfully  imposed  upon  the  exercise  of  privileges  within  the  taxing 
power  of  the  State  or  Nation,  the  measure  of  such  tax  may  be  the  income  from  the  property  of  the  corporation, 
although  a  part  of  such  income  is  derived  from  property  in  itself  nontaxable."  At  p.  163.  To  this  extent  the 
Pollock  case  (157  U.  S.  429)  was  modified. 


64 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


from  corporate  profits  all  interest  received  on  State  and  local 
obKgations. 

Interest  received  on  Federal  securities  has  likewise  been  exempt  in 
order  ''to  keep  faith"  with  the  declaration  of  exemption  usually  con- 
tained in  the  various  acts  under  which  some  obligations  were  issued. 
The  exemption  clause  has  usually  been  believed  to  have  enabled  the 
Federal  Government  to  obtain  loans  at  lower  interest  rates,  but  it 
is  a  moot  question  whether  the  revenue  gained — through  lower  interest 
rates — is  less  or  greater  than  the  revenue  lost — through  tax  exemption. 

In  1917  natural  persons  were  required  for  surtax  purposes  to  include 
in  their  taxable  net  income  all  interest  received  on  Federal  obligations 
unless  such  interest  was  specifically  exempt  under  the  act  authorizing 
the  issue  of  such  obligations — namely,  all  United  States  bonds,  except 
pre-war  issues,  and  securities  issued  by  Federal  instrumentalities 
(except  Federal  land  banks,  joint-stock  land  banks,  and  intermediate 
credit  banks).  Tliis  provision  did  not  apply  to  corporations.  In 
1933,  however,  the  interest  received  upon  Federal  obligations,  which 
was  subject  to  the  surtax  on  individuals,  became  subject  to  the 
present  excess-profits  tax  on  corporations.  As  will  be  pointed  out  in 
the  following  chapter,  this  change  was  relatively  unimportant  since  the 
corporations  obtaining  considerable  income  from  such  sources  are  large 
in  size  and  consequently  are  not  likely  to  pay  any  excess-profits  tax 
at  all. 

The  aggregate  amount  of  interest  received  by  corporations  from 
governmental  securities  has  been  very  substantial  and  in  fact  has 
been  increasing  in  recent  years.  In  1937  corporations  with  net  income 
reported  receipts  from  governmental  securities  in  the  amount  of 
$429,000,000,  while  individuals  reported  at  least  $301,000,000. 
Since  individuals  are  not  required  to  report  their  income  from  wholly 
tax-exempt  securities,  it  is  obvious  that  the  latter  figure  involves  a 
substantial  underestimate.  The  estimated  distribution  of  tax- 
exempt  securities  by  classes  of  holders  is  shown  in  the  following  table, 
as  of  June  30,  1937: 


Table  VI. — Estimated  distribution  of  tax-exeinpt  securities  by  classes  of  holder. 

June  30,  1937 

[In  billions  of  dollars] 


Wholly  exempt 

"Partially 
exempt" 

U.S. 
Govern- 
ment 
and 
Federal 
instru- 
men- 
talities 

State 
and 
local 

Federal 
instru- 
men- 
talities 

U.S. 
Govern- 
ment 

Total 

Government  and  their  agencies,  trust  funds,  sinking 
funds,  and  investment  funds  and  Federal  Reserve 
banks 

4.3 

2.8 
1.8 
.8 

A 

0.8 
.3 

3.5 
5.9 

W 

.3 

.1 

2.9 

6.5 
8.7 
3.7 

.8 
2.1 

.4 
6.8 

15.1 

Active  banks,  excluding  mutual  savings  banks 

Insurance  companies 

17.7 
6.8 

other  corporations             .  .  . 

.1 

2.8 

Mutual  savings  banks 

3.2 

other  tax-exempt  institutions       .  - 

1.0 

Individuals 

1.0 

19.0 

Total 

19.3 

2.2 

15.1 

29.0 

65.6 

Source:  Hearings  before  the  House  Ways  and  Means  Committee,  76th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  on  Proposed  Legis- 
lation Relating  to  Tax-exempt  Securities,  p.  29.  More  recent  figures  (as  of  June  1938)  for  Federal  securities 
may  be  found  in  the  Treasury  Bulletin  for  February,  1939,  p.  22. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  g5 

Taking  all  net-income  corporations  as  a  group,  the  magnitude  of  the 
credit  for  governmental  interest  claimed  by  corporations  under  the 
Federal  normal  corporation  income  tax  varies  directl^^  with  corporate 
size — the  larger  the  corporation,  the  larger  the  credit  for  Government 
interest.  See  chart  XV.  This  size  variation  is  by  no  means  as 
pronounced  as  the  size  variation  of  the  credit  for  intercorporate  divi- 
dends, although  in  recent  years  it  has  become  more  accentuated. 
This  tendency  is  readily  evident  from  a  comparison  of  the  1936-37 
patterns  with  that  of  the  3  previous  years  (1933-35). 

When  the  size  patterns  are  broken  down  by  industries  (see  charts 
XVI  and  XVII),  however,  it  is  found  that  the*^Government  interest  is 
of  great  importance  only  to  the  financial  group  of  corporations  where 
it  equals — if  not  exceeds — the  credit  for  intercorporate  dividends.  It 
was  relatively  of  no  importance  to  other  major  industries  or  to  the 
various  manufacturing  industries. ^^ 

By  exempting  Government  interest  from  taxation  under  the  normal 
tax  the  Federal  revenue  acts  have,  by  design  or  not,  encouraged  the 
large  financial  corporations  to  acquire  extensive  holdings  in  govern- 
mental securities. 


'S  It  should  be  pointed  out  that  the  area  on  the  graphs  technically  does  not  wholly  consist  of  credits  for 
governmental  interest  but  also  includes  a  credit  for  the  amount  of  the  excess-profits  tax. 


CHAPTER  V 

FEDERAL  TAXATION  OF  'EXCESS  PROFITS"  AND 
UNDISTRIBUTED  PROFITS 

The  Federal  normal  corporation  income  tax,  which  was  considered 
at  length  in  the  two  previous  chapters,  is  only  one  out  of  several 
Federal  taxes  based  upon  or  related  to  corporate  profits.  Although 
in  magnitude  the  normal  tax  accounts  for  the  major  share  of  both 
Federal  revenues  derived  from  corporate  profits  (85  percent  in  1936-37) 
and  tax  paj^ments  made  by  individual  corporations.  The  excess- 
profits  tax  and  the  surtax  on  undistributed  profits,  however,  have  had 
important  effects  upon  corporate  attitudes,  profits,  and  methods  of 
financing,  and  these  effects  have  varied  with  corporate  size  and  the 
nature  of  the  industries. 

EXCESS-PROFITS  TAX!    PREMIUM  ON  THE  PREDICTABILITY  OF  CORPORATE 

PROFITS 

The  present  excess-profits  tax,  which  was  initially  enacted  by  the 
National  Industrial  Hecovery  Act  of  1933,  is  an  excess-profits  tax  in 
name  only,  thoroughly  unlike  its  namesake  of  the  war  period.^  Essen- 
tially, the  present  excess-profits  tax  is  the  lesser  of  a  pair  of  Siamese 
twins,  the  better  half  of  which  is  the  capital-stock  tax  enacted  at  the 
same  time,  and  functions  as  a  whipping  boy  for  the  latter.  The 
capital-stock  tax  of  1933  was  imposed  ''upon  every  domestic  corpora- 
tion with  respect  to  carrying  on  or  doing  business  for  any  part  of 
such  year,''  at  the  rate  of  ''one  dollar  per  thousand  dollars  of  the 
adjusted  declared  value  of  its  capital  stock." 

The  corporation  may  choose  any  value  of  the  capital  to  be  declared, 
but  if  the  declared  value  was  excessive  in  relation  to  the  corporation's 
earnmg  capacity  it  found  itself  subject  to  an  excess-profits  tax  in 
1933-35  of  5  percent  of  all  profits  in  excess  of  12}^  percent  of  its  declared 
capitalization  and,  in  1936,  of  6  and  12  percent  of  those  profits  which 
were  10  and  15  percent,  respectively,  in  excess  of  declared  capital. 
Having  once  made  a  declaration  of  capital,  it  was  assumed  that  such 
a  declaration  would  be  more  or  less  bmdmg  on  the  corporation  for  a 
definite  time,  subject  to  a  few  adjustmients  of  a  very  specific  character. 
As  a  matter  of  fact,  however,  the  corporations  have  been  able  to  make 
a  redeclaration  of  capital  in  1934  and  1936.  The  1938  act  introduced 
the  concept  of  a  3-year  period  for  which  the  declaration  of  capital 
should  be  binding,  and  of  course  afforded  an  opportunity  for  a  new 
declaration.  Notice,  however,  that  in  1939  and  1940,  a  corporation 
was  allowed  to  revise  its  declaration  upward,  thus  miuiimizing  the 
excess-profits  tax,  and,  of  course,  in  1941  a  new  3 -year  declaration  is 
scheduled  to  be  made. 


See  appendix  A. 

67 


gg  OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POAVER 

Since  the  corporation  may  freely  report  any  capitalization  figure 
that  suits  its  needs,  it  is  to  its  advantage  to  select  a  figure  which  is 
approximately  8  times  (1933-35)  or  10  times  (1936  and  subsequent 
years)  its  expected  earnings  during  the  coming  years.  If  the  capital- 
ization figure  is  higher  than  this  ratio  to  earnings  its  capital  stock  tax 
is  pro  rata  heavier  than  it  need  be  in  order  to  avoid  payment  of  an 
excess-profits  tax.  If  the  capitalization  figure  is  less  than  this  ratio 
to  corporate  earnings,  the  resultmg  lightness  of  the  capital  stock  tax 
will  be  more  than  offset  by  an  excess-profits  tax.  It  is  always  prefer- 
able to  pay  the  capital-stock  tax — at  the  rate  of  $1  per  thousand  of 
invested  capital,  which  is  the  equivalent  of  a  tax  at  1  percent  of  taxable 
net  mcome — to  paying  the  excess-profits  tax  at  the  rate  of  6  to  12 
percent  of  taxable  net  income  provided  the  future  earnings  are  given. 

The  selection  of  favorable  capitalization  figures  depends  obviously 
on  the  accuracy  with  which  earnmgs  may  be  forecasted,  a  factor  which 
varies  with  the  economic  skill  of  the  corporate  managers,  the  stability 
or  fluctuation  of  corporate  profits  in  difl'erent  industries,  and  the 
chances  of  a  particular  corporation  to  make  profits  in  any  given  year. 
If  in  doubt  the  corporate  managers  may  prefer  to  avoid  or  reduce  a 
present  tax  liability  (the  capital-stock  tax)  to  a  contingent  liability 
(the  excess-profits  tax)  if  tiieir  profit  equation  should  turn  out  better 
than  they  expected.  It  must  not  be  overlooked,  however,  that  the 
rate  of  the  excess-profits  tax  is  of  a  very  high-powered  character  com- 
pared to  the  mild  rate  of  the  capital  stock  tax,  so  that  an  underpay- 
ment of  the  capital-stock  tax  may  result  in  an  exceedingly  high  excess- 
profits  tax,  while  an  overpayment  of  the  capital  stock  v/ill  not 
ordinarily  invojve  large  amounts. 

The  interlocking  operation  of  the  Federal  capital  stock  and  excess- 
profits  taxes  are  shown  graphically  in  chart  XVIII.  The  plotted  line 
of  the  diagram  shows  the  m.agnitude  of  the  combined  capital  stock 
and  excess-profits  taxes  measured  as  percentages  of  net  income  ac- 
cording to  different  assumptions  as  to  the  relationship  of  declared 
capitalization  and  net  income.^  It  is  obvious  from  this  chart  that  the 
corporation's  capital-stook-excess-profits  taxes  are  miiiunized — at 
1  percent  of  net  income — if  a  capital  stock  tax  is  paid  upon  a  declared 
capital  10  times  earnings.  It  is  equally  obvious  that,  if  the  corpora- 
tion is  apt  to  err  in  forecasting  profits  upon  which  to  file  a  declaration  of 
capital,  it  is  best  to  err  toward  an  overdeclaration  rather  than  toward 
an  underdeclaration.  An  underdeclaration  of  capital,  and  consequent 
underpayment  of  the  capital  stock,  leads  to  an  excess-profits  tax  of 
rapidly  increasing  magnitude.  Assuming  constant  earnings,  an 
underdeclaration  of  10  percent  is  equivalent  to  an  overdeclaration  of 
50  percent,  an  underdeclaration  of  20  percent  is  equivalent  to  an  over- 
declaration  of  100  percent,  an  underdeclaration  of  30  percent  is 
equivalent  to  an  overdeclaration  of  180  percent,  an  underdeclaration 
of  40  percent  is  equivalent  to  an  overdeclaration  of  260  percent,  an 
underdeclaration  of  50  percent  is  equivalent  to  an  overdeclaration 
of  400  percent,  an  underdeclaration  of  60  percent  is  equivalent  to  an 
overdeclaration  of  540  percent,  an  underdeclaration  of  70  percent  is 
equivalent  to  an  overdeclaration  of  680  percent,  an  underdeclaration 
of  SO  percent  is  equivalent  to  an  overdeclaration  of  820  percent,  an 
underdeclaration  of  90  percent  is  equivalent  to  an  overdeclaration  of 

2  For  the  formula,  which  was  derived  by  Orvis  A.  Schmidt,  see  appendix  B,  sec.  1. 


4 

1 

^ 

■^ 

4 

1 

0 

- 

/£    6 


(returns  with  net  income  only) 

BY    SIZE   CLASSES 

INTERLOCKING  OPERATION  OF  FEDERAL  CAPITAL  STOCK  TAX  AND  EXCESS-PROFITS  TAX 

Under  the  Revenue  Act  of  1936 

^^m    EXCESS-PROFITS   TAX   AS  i 

i^lH    OF    CORPORATE    PROFITS               ^     ""Jot«"'5"o™"" 

3 

y///A    EXCESS-PROFITS   TAX   AS            3       looooo  to  250000 

LESS  TAX   EXEMPT    DIVI-            ?    i  SSS  2SS  ™  .VooVooo 
OENDS   AND   GOVERNMENT              S  iS  SSoSSS  ?S  "o'o'oVo'o'o 
INTEREST                                          9n>vE«  sSobo.Mo— * — 
10    o»eR   100.000.000 

5 

R^^SSQ    ESTIMATED  CAPITAL    STOCK 
m^e^    TAXES   AS  ft  OF   CORPORATE 
PROFITS 

1 

V 

L 

^^^H^^^rsl^H  !^H 

s 

\ 

^^^^H^^^^^^l         v^^l      nl^^l 

^ 

■^1  ^^^H       P^       "^H 

1 

1    \                                                                                                                                   " 

^1       ^™                    1 

n 

r\ 

MIHBWB 

\, 

' 

oflia    td      Bsaaa              ei      m^^^"""^^^ 

\ 

,ZH-^(,lSSt<    l231Se7S9k    IZ345b7eSt    U34JC7e  910/ 1 3  4  5  6  7S  9,0 

\ 

1933               1934              1935               1936               1937 

\ 

SOURCE 

:     Computed  from  Statistics  of   Income  J 

\ 

h^                                 ^ 

FOR  Respect  1 

VE   YEARS 

p- 

"^"^1 — \ — 

D0-40-I3i 

OEPARTV.ENT  CF  COW.fERCE 
262698—41— No.  9      (Face  p.  69) 


8  10  12 

DECLARED    CAPITALIZATION    Tl 


14  |£  |8  20 

rs  NET  INCOME  (FOR  EXCESS  PROFITS  1 


22 
PURPOSES) 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


69 


I 


960  percent,  while  a  declaration  of  zero  capital  v/ill  subject  the  cor- 
poration to  an  excess-profits  tax  equal  in  magnitude  to  an  overdeclara- 
tion  of  capital  of  1,100  percent. 

It  is  unfortunately  not  possible  at  the  present  time  to  examine  for 
actual  cases  the  interlocking  efi'ects  of  the  Federal  capital  stock  tax 
and  the  excess-profits  tax  upon  the  profits  of  corporations  of  various 
sizes  and  industries,  since  there  are  no  data  available  on  the  size  and 
industrial  character  of  corporations  choosing  to  pay  the  capital-stock 
tax  and  by  what  amount,  or  choosing  not  to  pay  it.  It  is  believed 
possible,  however,  that  certain  crude  estunates  can  be  made  of  the 
magnitude  of  the  capital  stock  tax  from  the  present  data  on  the 
excess-profits  tax  available  in  Statistics  of  Income.  The  results  of 
these  estimates  are  presented  in  chart  XVIII,  for  ail  corporations  with 
net  income,  classified  by  size  of  assets  for  the  period  1933-37.^ 

From  this  chart  it  appears  that  the  excess-profits  tax  shows  a  very 
m.arked  tendency  to  vary  inversely  with  corporate  size,  while  the 
capital  stock  tax  pattern  characteristically  exhibits  only  slight  size 
variations.  The  regressivity  ^  of  the  excess-profits  tax  has  been  stead- 
ily mounting  since  1934,  so  that  in  1937  the  efiective  tax  rate  ranged 
from  1.7  percent  in  the  case  of  corporations  with  assets  under  $50,000 
dov/n  steadily  step-by-step  to  less  than  two-tenths  of  1  percent  in  the 
case  of  corporations  with  assets  over  $50,000,000.  In  1933-35  the 
range  of  the  regression  did  not  exceed  1  percent  of  corporate  profits 
while  in  1937  the  range  vv as  more  than  1.5  percent.  Stated  differently, 
the  magnitude  of  the  excess-profits  tax  paid  by  the  smallest  corporations 
was  more  than  eight  times  that  of  the  excess-profits  tax  paid  by  the 
largest  corporations.  This  chart  indicates  that  the  regression  of  the 
excess-profits  tax,  standing  alone,  is  hardly  offset  by  the  interlocking 
capital-stock  tax,  because  of  the  grossly  disparate  rate  structure  of 
the  two  taxes. 

The  chart  also  shows  clearly  that  the  credits  for  corporate  profits 
derived  from  intercorporate  dividends  and  for  Government  ^  interest 
are  quite  insignificant  in  the  operation  of  the  excess-profits  tax,  and 
naturally  so.  The  m_agnitude  of  the  excess-profi.ts  tax  varies  inversely 
with  the  corporate  size — that  is,  the  larger  the  corporation  the  smaller 
its  excess-profits  tax  (the  excess-profits  tax  may  be  wholly  nonextant 
in  the  larger  size  classes) — whereas  the  relative  magnitude  of  cor- 
porate profits  derived  from  intercorporate  dividends  and  Govern- 
ment interest  for  which  special  credits  may  be  available  under  the 
revenue  act,  varies  directly  with  corporate  size^that  is,  the  larger 
the  corporation,  the  more  likel}^  it  is  to  obtain  a  relatively  larger 
amount  of  its  profits  from  mtercorporate  dividends  and  Government 
interest. 

3  For  the  method  of  estimating  the  magnitude  of  the  capital-stock  tax,  see  appendix  B,  sec.  2. 

^  The  terms  "regressivity"  "regression,"  and  "regressive"  as  used  throughout  this  chapter  refer  to  the 
inverse  relationship  between  the  magnitude  of  the  tax  ratios  and  corporate  size.  In  other  words  these 
terms  mean  only  that  the  tax  rato  is  smallest  on  the  large  corporations  and  largest  on  the  small  corporations, 
and  nothing  more  is  meant,  or  implied,  in  this  connection. 

5  The  credit  for  Governm.ent  interest  under  the  excess-profits  tax  does  not  include  interest  received  on 
the  United  States  saving  bonds  and  Treasury  bonds  ov/ned  in  principal  amount  of  over  $5,000  and  obliga- 
tions of  instrumentalities  of  the  United  States  which  were  not  exempt  from  taxation  by  the  respective 
congressional  acts  authorizing  the  issurance  of  such  obligations.  Such  partially  tax-exempt  interest 
in  1937  amounted  to  $201,477,000  while  wholly  tax-exempt  interest  on  governmental  securities  (State  and 
local  obligaiions,  etc.)  amounted  to  $210,320,000.  It  also  should  be  noted  that  the  credit  for  Government 
interest  allowable  under  the  normal  tax  and  the  surtax  on  undistributed  profits  has  never  included  Gov- 
ernment interest  of  either  character  (except  under  the  excise  tax  of  1909). 


262698— 41— No.  9- 


70  CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  P0^^  ER 

The  general  pattern  of  regressivity  exhibited  by  the  excess-profits 
tax  for  all  corporations  taken  as  a  group,  is  largely  confirmed  in  the 
industry-by-industry  analysis  shown  in  chart  XIX.  In  only  one 
industry  (tobacco)  does  the  excess-profits  tax  appear  to  exhibit  no 
size  variation,  while  in  another  industry  (rubber)  the  effective  rate 
of  the  excess-profits  tax  on  the  medium-sized  corporations  appears 
heavier  than  on  the  smaller  corporations.  In  all  other  industries  the 
excess-profits  tax  appeared  markedly  regressive  in  1937,  The  re- 
gressivity of  the  excess-profits  tax  is  particularly  accentuated  in  con- 
struction, forest  products,  stone,  clay,  and  glass,  where  the  rate  on 
the  sm.aller  corporations  (with  assets  under  $100,000)  is  more  than 
20  times  that  on  the  largest  corporations,  while  in  the  case  of  motor 
vehicles  the  rate  on  the  smallest  corporations  is  31  times  the  rate  on 
the  larger  corporations  (with  assets  from  $5,000,000  to  $10,000,000). 
With  the  single  exception  of  construction  (which  has  no  corporations 
with  assets  above  $10,000,000)  the  effective  rates  of  the  excess  profits 
in  the  largest  size  classes  was  so  small  that  they  could  not  be  graph- 
ically shown. 

Chart  XX  presents  a  m^ore  detailed  industrial  picture  of  the  con- 
siderable variation  in  the  relative  magnitude  of  the  excess-profits  tax 
in  1937.  In  fact  this  diagram  shov/s  that  the  differences  among  in- 
dustries in  the  ratio  of  the  excess-profits  tax  to  corporate  profits  in 
1937  were  fully  as  great  as  the  size  difl'erences.  The  highest  ratio  for 
an  industry  (air  transportation)  was  2.5  percent  and  the  lowest;  (tele- 
phone and  telegraph)  was  less  than  0.05  percent.  The  excess-profits 
tax  was  largest  on  construction,  mining,  heavy  industry  (e.  g.,  ma- 
chinery and  tools,  railroad  equipment),  air  and  water  transportation — 
all  industries  characterized  by  fluctuating  profits.  The  excess-profits 
tax  was  lowest  on  various  public  utilities— such  as  telephone  and 
telegraph,  railroads,  electric  light  and  powcr^ — on  consumers'  goods 
industries — such  as  tobacco,  shoes,  and  food  products.  Other  indus- 
tries typically  organized  as  large-scale  enterprises  report  low  excess- 
profits  taxes — banks,  motion-picture  producers,  uivestment  trusts, 
anthracite  coal,  chemicals.  The  effect  of  the  tax  upon  other  specific 
industries  is  apparent  from  an  inspection  of  the  chart  and  need  not 
be  further  elaborated  here. 

Although  the  excess-profits  tax  is  usually  small  in  actual  dollars 
and  cents,  it  is  vvithout  question  a  very  regressive  tax  on  corporate 
profits.  Yet  its  rate  structure  contains  a  slight  graduation — 6  to 
12  percent — based  on  the  amount  of  profits  in  excess  of  a  stated  pro- 
portion (10  and  15  percent,  respectively)  to  declared  capital.  Such 
data  as  are  at  hand  (see  chart  XVIII)  do  not  indicate  that  the  capital- 
stock  tax  compensates  or  neutralizes  these  regrevssive  tendencies  to 
any  noticeable  degree. 

SURTAX   ON    UNDISTRIBUTED   PROFITS:    PREMIUM   OX   THE    DISTRIBUTION 
OF    CORPORATE    PROFITS 

During  1936  and  1937  the  Federal  Revenue  Act  imposed  on  cor- 
porations retaining  the  greater  share  of  their  profits,  a  tax,  additional 
to  the  normal  tax,  ranging  from  7  to  27  percent  in  accordance  with 
the  relative  magnitude  of  undistributed  profits.  In  1938  and  1939 
the  tax  rate  of  the  undistributed  profits  was  nominal  (2.5  percent). 
Starting  with  1940,  when  even  this  merest  remnant  disappeared,  the 


n^i  »BBrj 


m 


I 


JXAT  2rH05>'^ 


TUO 


EOERAL   EXCESS-PROFITS 
CASH   DIVIDENDS   PAN 


UNDISTRIBUTED   PROFITS   TAX   PAYMENTS, 
D   CREDITS   FOR   INVESTMENT   INCOME, 
INDUSTRIES.   1937 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


71 


Chart  XIX 

FEDERAL    EXCESS-PROFITS    TAX   PAYMENTS    OF    CORPORATIONS    OF    VARYING   SIZE 
CLASSES  AND  INDUSTRIES,  1937  (RETURNS  WITH  NET  INCOME  ONLY) 


BSii^;'i'i-^:ai 


ASSET    SIZE    CLASSES 

UNDER     *50.000 

»50,000  TO  *I00.000 

100,000   TO   250.000 

250,000  TO   500.000 

500,000  TO  1.000.000 

i. 000.000  TO  5.000.000 

5.000.000  TO  lO.OOC.OOO 

10.000.000  TO    50  000  000 

£0.000.000  TO  100,000.000 

OVER   100.000,000 


234  567  3  910 


!2a45GTfi9IO 

PETROL- 


si 


2345678910 
STONE- 

CLAY- 

_6LASS  


LEGEND 


0  -  No  Tax 


]  Excess-profits  Tax  .as  ^  of 
Corporate  Profits 

i  Excess-profits  Tax  as  ^  of 
Corporate  Profits  less 
Credits  for  Intercorporate 
Dividends  and  Government 
Interest 


123*5678910        I2345fc789«0 

METALS  MOTOR 

VEHICLES 


X  -  No  Cases 

Y  -  Less  than  .05^      D.P.40-/33 


Source:  Computed  from  the  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue. 
Department  of  Commerce. 


72  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Federal  Revenue  Act  has  become  largely  unconcerned  with  corporate 
policies  as  to  the  retention  or  distribution  of  profits  to  stockholders. 
This  statement  must  be  modified  by  one  important — at  least  poten- 
tially important — proviso:  Where  the  ' 'unreasonable"  magnitude  of 
retained  profits  may  be  taken  as  prima  facie  evidence  of  a  ''purpose 
of  preventing  the  imposition  of  the  surtax  upon  its  shareholders," 
the  corporation  m-.ay  find  itself  subject  to  a  surtax  of  25  to  35  per- 
cent on  the  undistributed  net  income,  under  section  102  of  interna] 
revenue  laws.^  To  this  extent  the  undistributed-profits  tax  has 
now  (September  1940)  become  an  episode  in  the  history  of  Federal 
income  taxation.  But  it  is  not  just  an  episode  filed  away  in  the 
archives  for  the  purpose  of  accumulating  dust.  The  undistributed- 
profits  tax  v/as  an  experiment  in  corporate-tax  reform  v/hose  record 
of  performance  deserves  careful  scrutiny. 

As  originally  conceived  in  the  President's  message  sent  to  Congress 
on  Alarch  3,  1936,  and  to  a  substantia.!  extent  as  drafted  in  the  House 
bill/  the  new  tax  plan  contemplated  the  outright  abolition  of  all 
existing  Federal  taxes  based  on  or  related  to  capital  profits — i.  e,, 
the  normal  tax,  the  capital  stock  tax,  and  the  excess-profits  tax — 
and  the  substitution  therefor  of  a  new  tax  of  a  graduated  character 
on  that  part  of  "corporate  income  (including  dividends  from  other 
corporations)  which  is  not  distributed  as  earned  *  *  *."  The 
new  tax  was  designed  to  (a)  remove  the  "existing  difference  between 
corporate  taxes  and  those  imposed  on  owners  of  unincorporated 
businesses,"  (b)  prevent  avoidance  of  existing  surtaxes  by  natural 
persons  who  can  afford  to  leave  corporate  earnings  undistributed, 
and   (c)  reduce  corporate  savings. 

The  problem  of  the  undistributed  profits  of  corporations,  as  Com- 
missioner Helvering  pointed  out,  was  "no  new  development." 

It  has  received  the  attention  and  support  of  students  of  taxation  from  the 
earliest  days  of  income  taxation  in  the  IJnited  States.  Its  principles  were  in- 
corporated in  our  first  income-tax  law,  1862-71,  when  Congress  provided  that 
the  gains  and  profits  of  corporations  should  be  included  in  the  annual  taxable 
gains,  profit,  or  income  of  any  person  entitled  to  them,  whether  divided  or  un- 
divided. Shortly  before  and  while  the  Revenue  Act  of  1921  was  under  consider- 
ation, a  proposal  identical  in  principle  with  the  President's  suggestion  received 
the  support  of  many  representatives  of  organized  business,  Members  of  Con- 
gress, and  the  Treasury  Department.  The  principle  v/as  recommended  by  Sec- 
retary of  the  Treasury  Houston  in  his  annual  report  for  the  year  1920.  In  some- 
what modified  form,  it  was  incorporated  in  a  bill  passed  by  the  Senate  in  1924. ^ 

The  Senate,  however,  was  reluctant  at  one  stroke  to  abandon 
existing  Federal  taxes  on  corporate  profits — the  normal  tax  on  cor- 
poration income  being  highly  productive  from  a  revenue  viewpoint — 
and  amended  the  House  bill  by  (a)  retaining  all  existing  taxes  on 

6  Under  T.  T>.  4914  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue  has  indicated  that  its  tax  auditors  will  closely  scruti- 
ni:^-e  the  foUo'.vin'i'  elasses  of  corporations  in  order  to  determine  the  applicability  of  S'^c.  102: 

"(1)  Corporations  which  have  not  distributed  at  least  70  percent  of  their  earnings  as  taxable  dividends. 

"(2)  Corporations  which  have  invested  earnings  in  securities  or  other  properties  unrelated  to  their  normal 
business  activities. 

"(3)  Corporations  which  have  advanced  sums  to  officers  or  shareholders  in  the  form  of  loans  out  of  undis- 
tributed profits  or  surplus  from  which  taxable  dividends  might  have  been  declared. 

"(4)  Corporations,  a  majority  of  whose  stock  is  held  by  a  family  group  or  other  small  group  of  individuals, 
or  bv  a  trust  or  trusts  for  the  benefit  of  such  groups. 

"(5)  Corporations  the  distributions  of  which,  while  exceeding  70  percent  of  their  earnings,  appear  to  be 
inadequate  when  considered  in  connection  with  the  nature  of  the  business  or  the  financial  position  of  th? 
corporation  or  corporations  with  accumulations  of  cash  or  other  quick  assets  which  appear  to  be  beyond  the 
reasonable  needs  of  the  business." 

Evidence  is  lacking  at  the  moment  as  to  efficacy  of  sec.  102  and  its  administrative  enforcement. 

7  Union  Calendar  No.  944  of  the  74th  Cong.,  2d  sess. 

8  Senate  Finance  Committee,  hearings  on  the  19.36  Revenue  Act,  pp.  12-13. 

For  a  fuller  review  of  the  legislative  background  of  the  problem  of  undistributed  profits  see  the  statement 
of  Herman  Oliphant  reproduced  in  appendix  C  of  this  report. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  73 

corporate  profits  with  some  modifications  as  noted  below  and  (b) 
superimposing  thereupon  a  new  surtax  on  the  undistributed  profits 
of  corporation.  The  new  surtax  contained  a  severely  graduated  rate 
structure  ranging  from  7  percent  to  27  percent  of  that  portion  of  cor- 
porate profits  (including  all  intercorporate  dividends  received  and 
excluding  interest  received  on  Government  securities)  which  was  not 
distributed  during  the  year  as  taxable  dividends.  The  new  surtax 
applied  to  all  corporations  not  otherwise  tax  exempt  except  the 
following: 

1.  Banks. 

2.  Insurance  companies. 

3.  Foreign  corporations. 

4.  Corporations  operating  in  the  United  States  possession's. 

5.  China  Trade  Act  corporations. 

6.  Joint-stock  land  banks. 

7.  Bankrupt,  insolvent,  or  receivership  corporations. 

The  first  two  problems  wliich  the  undistributed-profits  tax  aimed 
at  originally  rose  out  of  the  constitutional  dictate  that  '^  unrealized 
income"  is  not  'Haxable  income/'  at  least  as  conventionally  construed 
in  Supreme  Court  decisions.^  The  undistributed  profits  of  corpora- 
tions cannot  be  taxed  to  the  stockholder,  the  courts  have  held,  be- 
cause he  cannot  dispose  of  such  income  until  it  is  realized,  i.  e.,  paid 
out  to  him  as  dividends.  A  partner  on  the  other  hand,  is  taxed  on 
his  pro  rata  profits  of  the  partnership,  irrespective  of  the  fact  whether 
they  are  retained  in  the  business  or  paid  out.  Again  legal  logic  focuses 
its  attention  on  the  power  of  disposal. 

At  the  outset  it  must  be  clearly  recognized  that  the  undistributed- 
profits  tax  as  finally  enacted  by  the  1936  revenue  act — ^'^a  grating 
compromise  that  pleases  neither  believers  nor  disbelievers"  ^° — could 
not  be  expected  substantial^  to  correct  existing  tax  inequalities  be- 
tween corporate  and  noncorporate  enterprise,  for  the  simple  reason 
that  all  existing  taxes  on  corporate  profits  (i.  e.,  the  normal  tax,  the 
excess-profits  tax,  and  the  capital-stock  tax)  were  retained  in  unaltered 
form. 

The  judicial  attitude  toward  taxing  ''unrealized  income"  makes  it 
possible  for  a  steeply  progressive  personal  income  tax  operating  in 
conjunction  with  a  moderately  progressive  or  flat  corporation  income 
tax  to  favor  one  type  of  taxpayers  at  the  expense  of  other  taxpayers. 
The  type  favored  is  of  course  individual  stockholders  in  corporations 
wliich  do  not  fully  and  promptly  distribute  their  earnings  in  the  form 
of  dividends.  The  undistributed-profits  tax  of  1936  was  designed  to 
diminish  this  favoritism  by  subjecting  the  undistributed  profits  of 
corporations  to  a  special  tax. 

Further,  it  may  be  contended,  corporate  self-financing  out  of  re- 
tained profits  and  depreciation  charges  dispenses  with  the  necessity 
for  resorting  to  the  capital  market.  The  range  of  decision  is  thus 
narrowed  to  the  corporate  managers  themselves,  who  thus  avoid 
outside  check  and  approval  (i.  e.,  b}^  the  functionaries  and  institu- 
tions of  investment)  of  their  plans  for  expansion,  possibly  entailing 
waste  of  capital.  Such  short-circuiting  of  the  instrumentalities  of 
the  capital  market  also  precludes  effective  supervision  of  investment 
channels  by  the  Government.     It  should  be  pointed  out  that  the 

9  See  the  comprehensive  review  of  relevant  cases  in  Eoswell  Magill's  study  of  Taxable  IncomefClGSe). 

10  See  Willard  L.  Thorp  and  Edward  B.  George,  "An  Appraisal  of  the  Undistributed  Profits  Tax," 
Dun's  Review,  September  1937. 


74  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  PO^VER 

undistributed-profits  tax  of  1936  made  only  a  partial  approach  to  the 
problem  of  corporate  savings,  since  depreciation  funds  (which,  of 
course,  are  very  large)  were  completely  unaffected  by  the  new  tax. 
One  of  the  misfortunes  of  the  undistributed-profits  tax  of  1936,  it 
has  been  frequently  suggested,  was  that  it  was  enacted  at  a  time  when 
the  market  for  new  capital  issues  was  not  functioning  satisfactorily.^^ 

The  accumulation  of  criticism  ^^  against  the  tax  on  undistributed 
profits  lead  Congress  to  all  but  repeal  the  tax,  retaining  in  the  1938 
Revenue  Act  a  small  stump  of  2K  percent  of  the  undistributed  profits 
of  corporations  with  net  income  in  excess  of  $25,000.  Besides  thus 
exempting  the  smaller  corporations  (i.  e.,  with  net  incomes  of  not 
more  than  $25,000)  the  1938  act  also  expanded  the  scope  of  various 
credits  allowed  under  the  surtax,  including  the  reintroduction  of  the 
net  operating  loss  carr\^-over  provision  (in  effect  from  1919  through 
1932)  insofar  as  the  surtax  was  concerned.  A  credit  was  also  allowed 
for  ''amounts  used  or  irrevocably  set  aside  to  pay  or  to  retire  indebted- 
ness (existing  on  December  31,  1937)  of  any  kind,  if  such  amounts  are 
reasonable  with  respect  to  the  size  and  terms  of  such  indebtedness.'^ 
The  corporation  was  also  allowed  to  claim  ''a  consent  dividends  credit 
equal  to  such  portion  of  the  total  sum  agreed  to  be  included  in  the  gross 
income  of  shareholders  by  their  consents."  ^^  In  the  1939  act  (appli- 
cable to  1940)  the  surtax  on  undistributed  profits  was  completely 
abandoned. 

The  data  presently  available  are  inadequate  either  to  determine 
the  degree  to  which  the  new  tax,  by  forcing  distributions  of  corporate 
profits  into  the  hands  of  individuals,  implemented  the  surtax  on 
natural  persons,  or  to  indicate  the  efficacy  of  the  reforming  changes 
made  by  the  1938  act,  particular!}^  with  reference  to  the  exemption  of 
smaller  corporations  (i.  e.,  with  net  incomes  under  $25,000)  and  cor- 
porations desiring  to  retire  existing  indebtedness  and  with  reference  to 
the  employment  of  the  consent  dividends  device. ^"^  All  that  is  possible 
at  the  present  instance  is  to  examine  for  1936  and  1937  the  effect  of 
the  surtax  on  the  profits  of  corporations  of  varying  sizes  and  industrial 
activities,  and  to  determine  insofar  as  possible,  how  the  magnitude 
of  the  tax  varied  with  the  magnitude  of  dividends  distributed. 

The  undistributed-profits  tax  applied  to  all  corporate  profits  except 
interest  derived  from  governmental  securities.  Dividends  received 
from  other  corporations  were  included  in  net  income  to  the  full 
amount,   while   only   85   percent   of  intercorporate   dividends   were 

n  See  Gerhard  Colm,  The  1938  Revenue  Act,  Social  Research. 

"  The  House  Ways  and  Means  Committee  of  the  75th  Cong.,  3d  sess.,  summarized  the  criticism  of  the 
surtax  on  undistributed  profits  as  follows: 

"(1)  It  discourages,  in  many  cases,  legitimate  business  expansion,  and  therefore  has  an  adverse  effect  on 
employment. 

"(2)  It  puts  a  penalty  on  corporations  which  find  it  necessary  to  use  current  earnings  in  the  payment  of 
debts. 

"(3)  It  burdens  the  small  and  weak  corporation  more  than  the  large  and  financially  strong  corporation. 

"(4)  It  is  unfair  to  corporations  with  impaired  capital  which  under  State  law  cannot  legally  declare  divi- 
dends. 

"(5)  The  relief  provisions  of  existing  law  dealing  with  corporations  having  contracts  not  to  pay  dividends 
or  contracts  requiring  the  use  of  current  earnings  for  the  payment  of  debts  are  so  restrictive  as  to  provide 
relief  only  in  rare  cases. 

"Your  subcommittee  has  examined  these  complaints  and  believes  there  has  been  much  exaggeration  as  to 
hardships  in  the  great  majority  of  cases.  It  is  bf^lieved,  however,  that  a  substantial  number  of  cases  of 
hardship  exist  and  that  in  such  cases  there  is  merit  in  the  complaints.  It  appears,  however,  to  design  general 
relief  provisions  broad  enough  to  take  care  of  these  meritorious  cases  without  a  very  serious  loss  of  revenue." 
Revision  of  Revenue  Laws.  1938,  p.  12.. 

13  If  the  shareholder  who  makes  the  consent  Is  a  corporation,  the  amount  specified  in  the  consent  shall  be 
considered  as  part  of  its  earnings  or  profits  for  the  taxable  year  *  *  *  sec.  28.  Also  see  Regulations  101, 
arts.  26-27.  Note  that  the  1938  revenue  act  was  allowed  to  become  law  without  the  President's  signature  and 
that  the  President  issued  a  statement  criticizing  the  abandonment  of  the  undistributed-profits  tax  principle. 

»  See  sec.  27  of  the  1938  act. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  75 

included  in  net  income  for  the  normal  tax  and  the  excess-profits  tax. 
To  this  extent  it  is  apparent  that  the  sm^tax  on  midistributed  profits 
acted  somewhat  as  a  deterrent  to  intercorporate  afliiliations.  The 
undistributed-profits  tax,  however,  contained  no  restrictions  as  to  the 
taxable  character  of  the  recipient  of  dividends  paid  upon  Avliich  the 
distributing  corporation  claimed  credit.  In  other  words  it  was  irrele- 
vant whether  the  stockliolder  was  a  natural  person  (who  would  pay 
normal  and  surtaxes  upon  his  entire  dividend  income)  or  a  tax- 
exempt  corporation  (wliich  would  pay  no  normal  taxes  whatever). 
To  this  extent  the  purpose  of  forcing  corporate  profits  to  be  distributed 
into  the  hands  of  stockholders  and  there  taxed  under  the  individual 
income  tax  was  partially  defeated,  especially  in  cases  where  the  stock- 
holder fell  in  the  tax-exempt  category.  In  the  case  of  the  corporate 
stockholder  it  should  be  noted  that  it  would  of  course  be  subject  to 
the  surtax  on  midistributed  profits  (if  not  specifically  exempt)  upon 
the  entire  amount  of  its  dividend  income. ^^ 

Corporations  were  allowed  to  deduct  from  net  income,  so  defined, 
the  am.ounts  of  the  excess-profits  tax  and  the  normal  tax  paid  and  to 
take  credits  for  the  total  amount  of  taxable  dividends  distributed  and 
all  amounts  required  by  contracts  (executed  prior  to  May  1,  1936, 
and  expressl}'  dealing  with  the  payment  of  dividends)  'Ho  be  paid 
within  the  taxable  year  in  chscharge  of  a  debt,  or  to  be  irrevocably  set 
aside  within  the  taxable  year  for  the  discharge  of  a  debt."  ^^  These 
deductions  from  and  credits  against  net  income  resulted  in  ''undis- 
tributed net  income"  which  was  subject  to  a  special  surtax  ranging 
from  7  percent  to  27  percent  in  accordance  with  the  magnitude  of  such 
undistributed  net  income  in  relation  to  net  income  before  the  credits. 

In  the  case  of  banking  affiliates  subject  to  regulation  by  the  Board 
of  Governors  of  the  Federal  Reserve  System  and  in  the  case  of  national 
m.ortgage  association  created  under  title  III  of  the  National  Housing 
Act,  special  credits  were  respectively  available  for  the  "amount  of 
earnings  or  profits  which  *  *  *  j^^^g  been  devoted  by  such 
affiliate  during  the  taxable  year  to  the  acquisition  of  readily  m.arket- 
able  assets  other  than  bank  stock"  and  "the  am.ount  of  earnings  or 
profits  which  *  *  *  }ias  been  devoted  by  such  association 
during  the  taxable  year  to  the  acquisition  of  such  reserves  as  the 
Federal  Housing  Adm.inistrator  m.ay  require."  ^^ 

In  order  to  claim  a  credit  for  dividends  distributed  it  was  necessary 
for  the  corporation  to  establish  that  the  distribution  was  a  taxable 
dividend.  As  to  cash  dividends  no  legal  problem,  was  presented 
since  they  were  clearly  taxable  under  the  sixteenth  amendment  as 
construed  by  the  Suprem.e  Court.  Difficulties,  however,  did  exist 
with  respect  to  stock  dividends,  stem.m.ing  from,  the  celebrated  decision 
of  the  Supreme  Court  in  Eisner  v.  Macomber  ^^  which  held  that  a 
dividend  in  com.rnon  stock  issued  to  the  holder  of  com.m.on  stock 
was  not  income  within  the  nieaning  of  the  Constitution .  For  som.e  time 
it  was  felt,  and  the  revenue  acts  and  treasury  regulations  so  indicated, 

1'  In  Facing  the  Tax  Problem  it  is  suggested  that  the  undistributed-profits  tax  may  encourage  holding 
companies.    See  p:  180. 

'«  1930  act,  sec.  26  (c).  In  lieu  of  this  provision,  the  1938  act  provided  that  a  credit  could  be  claimed  for  all 
'"amounts  used  or  irrevocably  sot  aside  to  pay  or  to  [retire  indebtedness  (existing  on  Dec.  31,  1937,  and  evi- 
denced by  a  bond,  note,  debenture,  certificate  of  indebtedness,  mortgage,  debt  of  trust,  or  accepted  bill  of 
exchange)  of  any  kind,  if  such  amounts  are  reasonable  with  respect  to  the  size  and  terms  of  such  indebted- 
ness," sec.  27  (a). 

i'  See  sec.  26  (d-e)  of  the  1936  act.  The  1938  act  completely  exempted  all  rental  housing  corporations  from 
the  undistributed  profits  tax. 

J«252U.  S.  189(1920). 


76  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

that  all  stock  dividends  were  nontaxable.  During  1936  and  1937, 
however,  the  Supreme  Court  in  Koshland  v.  Helvering  ^^  held  preferred 
stock  distributed  to  the  holders  of  common  stock  was  taxable  incom.e, 
although  both  classes  of  stock  were  outstanding  at  the  tim.e  of  dis- 
tribution, but  not  held  in  equal  proportion,  and  in  Helvering  v. 
Gowan  ^^  held  taxable  common  stock  distributed  to  the  holders  of 
preferred  stock.  In  Regulations  103,  the  Treasury  has  sum.marized  the 
legal  position  of  stock  dividends  as  follov/s: 

The  distinction  between  a  stock  dividend  which  does  not,  and  one  which  does, 
constitute  income  to  the  shareholder  within  the  meaning  of  the  sixteenth  amend- 
ment to  the  Constitution  is  the  distinction  between  a  stock  dividend  which  works 
no  change  in  the  corporate  entity,  the  same  interest  in  the  samie  corporation  being 
represented  after  the  distribution  by  more  shares  of  precisely  the  same  character, 
and  a  stock  dividend  where  there  either  has  been  a  change  of  corporate  identity 
or  a  change  in  the  nature  of  the  shares  issued  as  dividends  whereby  the  propor- 
tional interest  of  the  shareholder  after  the  distribution  is  essentially  different 
from  his  former  interest.  A  stock  dividend  constitutes  income  if  it  gives  the 
shareholder  an  interest  different  from  that  which  his  former  stock  holdings 
represented.  A  stock  dividend  does  not  constitute  income  if  the  new  shares  confer 
no  different  rights  or  interests  than  did  the  old — the  new  certificates  plus  the  old 
representing  the  same  proportionate  interest  in  the  net  assets  of  the  corporation 
as  did  the  old.21 

Very  few  corporations,  however,  appear,  at  least  in  1936  and  1937, 
to  have  chosen  stock  dividends  in  preference  to  cash  dividends  as  a 
m.ethod  of  distribution  designed  to  satisfy  the  requirements  for  a 
credit  under  the  surtax  on  undistributed  profits.  Taking  all  corpora- 
tions with  net  incom.e  in  1936,  the  am.ount  of  cash  dividends  am.ounted 
to  $7,179,200,000  whereas  stock  dividends  amounted  to  $335,319,000 
or  approximately  4  percent  of  total  dividends  distributed.  In  1937, 
cash  dividends  am.ounted  to  $7,308,774,000  while  stock  dividends 
am.ounted  to  $170,945,000  or  2.3  percent  of  total  dividends  distributed. 

The  stock  dividends  distributed  in  1936-37  were  apparently  inade- 
ciuate  in  most  cases  to  satisfy  the  requirements  of  the  credit  under  the 
surtax,  at  least  insofar  as  indicated  by  available  data  on  a  sample 
number  of  corporations  subject  to  the  surtax.  In  1936  only  13.4 
percent  of  the  stock  dividends  reported  for  this  sample  were  claimed 
taxable  by  the  taxpayer  (before  audit  by  the  Treasury) — consisting 
largely  of  preferred  stock  distributed  to  the  holders  of  common  stock. '^ 
See  table  VII.  In  1937  the  percentage  of  taxable  stock  dividends  out 
of  total  stock  dividends  rose  to  37  percent  while  the  total  stock  divi- 
dends, as  already  indicated  in  the  previous  paragraph,  declined  from 
4  percent  of  total  dividends  distributed  in  1936  to  2.3  percent  in  1937. 
The  aggregate  result  was  a  slight  increase  in  the  relative  amount  of 
taxable  stock  dividends  out  of  total  taxable  distributions  from  0.6 
percent  in  1936  to  0.9  percent  in  1937.^3 

'-8  298U.  S.441  (1936). 
■-0  302TT.  ?.  238  (1937). 

21  Art.  115-7.    Tho  same  lans:u3?e  may  be  found  in  Regulations  94.  issued  under  the  revenue  act  of  1936. 

22  In  1936  the  corporation  income  tax  form  provided  no  direction  to  the  taxpayers  as  to  whether  particular 
types  of  noncash  distributions  were  taxable— and  hence  available  as  a  credit  under  the  surtax— or  nontax- 
able, while  in  1937  the  corporation  income-tax  form  specifically  indicated  that  such  a  distribution  should  not 
be  claimed  as  a  taxable  distribution  for  purposes  of  the  surtax. 

23  All  the  figures  in  this  paragraph  have  been  computed  from  a  special  tabulation  (made  available  by  the 
Division  of  Tax  Research  of  the  Treasury  Department)  of  corporation  income-tax  returns  filing  the  special 
schedule  ("N"  in  1936  and  "M"  in  1937.  of  form  1120)  on  the  composition  of  dividend  distribution  upon  which 
claims  for  the  dividend  credit  under  the  surtax  may  be  made. 


HTIW  eViHTJ 


■ 


Chart  XXI 

FEDERAL  SURTAX  ON  UNDISTRIBUTED  PROFITS  OF  CORPORATIONS  BY  SIZE  CLASSES  AND  MAJOR  INDUSTRIES,  1937  (RETURNS  WITH  NET  INCOME  ONLY)! 


Cosh  Dividends  c 


PERCENT     CORPORATIONS  MANUFACTURING 


SURTAX 

TRADE  SERVICE 


ASSET    SIZE 

CLASSES 

100,000 

250,000 

5,000,000 

9 
10 

-'^S  - 

io'o,oo'o,ooo 

100,000,000 

CONSTRUCTION  PUBLIC  UTILITIES 


rf 


^ 

5 

" 

- 

- 

I 


%^  Wmmi 


PERCENT      CORPORATIONS  MANUFACTURING 


CASH  DIVIDENDS  PAID 

TRADE  SERVICE 


CONSTRUCTION  PUBLIC  UTILITIES 


1 

I  ^ 

1 

^ 


34S6789I0  123456789  10 


Source.  Computed  from  the  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue. 
Department  of  Commerce. 


J 

1 

1 

1 

23456789  10 


262698— 41— No.  9      (Face  p.  77)     No.l 


y/////Ayyy////yy///, 


^/a/^/. 


Ifiiii 

IsSSSSSSSSE 

i  igg-g-&s-§g-&s 


III  I 

fill 


m 


S  c 


CONCENIEATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


77 


Table  VII. —  Types  of  dividends  distributed  by  corporations  subject  to  the  surtax  on 
undistributed  profits,  1936-37 


[In  percent] 

193fi 

1937 

Cash 

94.19 
2.28 
2.20 
.49 
.10 
.37 
.10 
.09 
.20 

Assets                       -         -  --- - 

Obligations  of  corporations .- . 

\        99.15 

Optional  medium  (cash) . 

Treasury  stock                          -     -- 

Preferred  stock  on  common .  

Common  stock  on  preferred . 

I             85 

Preferred  stock  on  preferred  ... 

Optional  medium  (common  stock) ..-  .  

Total  taxable  distributions 

100. 00 

100  00 

Total  taxable  distributions 

96.50 
3.50 

98  6 

Nontaxable  stock  dividends ..-      _     __  

1.4 

Total  distributions 

100.  00 

100  00 

Source:  Computed  from  a  sample  tabulation  made  available  by  the  Treasury  Department  and  published 
in  less  detailed  form  in  the  Treasury  Bulletin  for  March,  1940. 


A  slight  size  variation  was  noticeable  in  1936  with  respect  to  cash 
distribution  as  compared  with  taxable  stock  dividends.  Corpora- 
tions with  large  net  incomes  (over  $5,000,000)  in  1936  distributed 
substantially  all  their  dividends  in  the  form  of  cash  (97  percent), 
whereas  corporations  with  relatively  small  incomes  (under  $50,000) 
preferred  to  distribute  at  least  one-eighth  of  their  dividend  (12.8  per- 
cent) in  forms  other  than  in  cash.^- 

Chart  XXI  shows  the  effect  of  the  undistributed  profits  tax  on  cor- 
porations of  varying  size  and  industries  in  1937.  The  surtax  is  meas- 
ured as  a  percent  of  compiled  net  profits  (a)  before  credits  and  (b)  after 
credits  for  the  amounts  of  the  normal  tax  and  the  excess-profits  tax 
and  the  interest  derived  from  governm-ental  securities,  while  the 
amount  of  cash  dividends  paid  out  has  been  shown  as  a  percentage  of 
the  total  profits. ^^  Stock  dividends  have  been  disregarded,  as  gen- 
erally constituting  a  nontaxable  distribution  upon  which  no  credit 
may  be  claimed  under  the  surtax.  It  is,  unfortunately,  not  possible 
to  show  the  effect  of  credits  for  written  contracts  restricting  payment 
of  dividends,  since  no  data  are  available  by  size  or  by  industries. 

From  these  charts  it  is  at  once  apparent  that  the  undistributed- 
profits  tax  operated  very  unevenly  in  the  different  size  and  industrial 
classes.  Taking  all  corporations  as  a  group  in  1937  the  magnitude 
of  the  undistributed  tax  tends  to  vary  inversely  with  corporate  size — 
that  is,  the  larger  the  corporation,  the  smaller  the  tax,  and  the  smaller 
the  corporation,  the  larger  the  tax.  This  pattern  generally  reflects  the 
complementary  pattern  of  the  distribution  of  dividends,  the  magnitude 
of  v/liich  varies  directly  with  the  corporate  size— that  is,  the  larger  the 
corporation,  the  greater  the  share  of  distributed  profits  and,  conversely, 
the  smaller  the  corporation  the  greater  the  share  of  undistributed 
profits. 

21  Also  see  Thorp  &  George,  op.  cit. 

25  The  amount  of  cash  dividends  paid  out  by  corpojations  in  a  given  size-industry  class  is  not  necessarily 
equivalent  to  the  aggregate  dividend  credit  claimed,  since  some  corporations  (esj^ecially  in  the  larger  size 
classes)  may  distribute  more  dividends  than  they  had  "adjusted  net  income." 


78  CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

When  the  size  pattern,  however,  is  broken  down  by  industries  it 
does  not  exliibit  as  clear  a  size  variation,  although  there  is  a  general 
tendency  in  most  cases  for  the  magnitude  of  the  undistributed-profits 
tax  to  be  higher  on  the  smaller  corporations  than  it  is  on  the  larger 
corporations.  But  this  tendency  is  by  no  means  invariable  and  is 
frequently  obliterated  by  the  tendency  for  the  medium-sized  corpora- 
tions to  report  the  highest  undistributed-profits-tax  ratio.  This 
analysis  will  be  presented  for  1936  and  1937  in  succession. 

Among  the  major  industries  in  1936,  the  undistributed-profits  tax 
appeared  fairly  heavy  on  the  smaller  corporations  in  construction, 
trade,  and  public  utilities,  while  in  manufacturing  and  service  the 
higher  effective  rates  of  the  surtax  appear  in  the  medium-sized  classes. 
In  mining  and  finance  the  undistributed-profits  tax  was  relatively  low, 
exhibiting  a  tendency  to  vary  inversely  with  corporate  size.  Among 
the  manufacturing  industries,  the  highest  rates  appear  frequently  in 
the  larger-size  classes,  particular^  in  beverages,  leather,  rubber, 
forest  products,  paper,  and  petroleum,  while  the  smaller  size  classes 
report  higher  rates  in  food,  tobacco,  clothing,  printing,  chemicals, 
stone-clay-glass,  metals,  and  motor  vehicles. 

The  charts  also  show,  in  most  cases,  the  essential  insignificance  of 
the  credits  for  Government  interest  and  for  the  amounts  of  the  normal 
and  excess-profits  taxes  that  were  allowable  under  the  surtax  on 
undistributed  profits.  Among  the  major  industries  this  credit  was  of 
substantial  importance  only  to  finance  where  large  holdings  in  govern- 
mental securities  account  for  a  major  share  of  corporate  profits.  By 
exempting  such  profits  from  the  surtax  on  undistributed  profits, 
corporate  investments  in  Government  obligations  were  encouraged. 
The  relative  unimportance  of  these  credits  among  the  larger  corpora- 
tions in  other  major  industries  reflects  the  lightness  of  the  surtax  of 
those  instances,  residting  from  the  substantial  cash  distribution  in 
corporate  profits.  Among  the  manufacturing  industries  the  credit 
was  likewise  relatively  insignificant  except  for  a  fev,^  of  the  larger-size 
classes — notably  clothing,  rubber,  forest  products,  and  petroleum. 

In  1937,  the  latest  year  for  wliich  data  are  available,  the  undis- 
tributed-profits tax  appears  to  have  operated  somewhat  less  unevenly 
than  it  did  in  1936.  For  example,  the  highest  effectiv^e  rate  in  1937 
for  any  size-industrial  class  was  8.9  percent  (beverages — seventh-size 
class)  whereas  ^n  1936  the  effectVe  rate  ranged  as  high  as  20.2  percent 
(paper — eighth-size  class).  Aside  from  the  greater  extremes  that 
characterize  the  1936  pattern,  the  1937  size  pattern  appears  to  closely 
approximate  that  shown  by  1936. 

In  trade,  public  utilities,  and  finance  the  pattern  is  one  of  general 
regressivity  with  the  highest  effective  rates  reported  for  the  smaller 
corporations  and  the  lowest  rates  reported  for  the  larger  corporations. 
In  the  case  of  manufacturing,  mining,  service,  and  construction,  on 
the  other  hand,  the  lugliest  eft'octive  rates  are  reported  for  the  medium- 
sized  corporations.  The  general  pattern  for  manufacturing  as  a 
whole  is  naturally  shown  for  most  manufacturing  industries.  How- 
ever, it  should  be  noted  that  the  pattern  is  progressive  in  the  case  of 
beverages  and  regressive  in  the  case  of  goods,  textiles,  clothing,  leather, 
and  chemicals.  These  variations,  of  course,  are  largely  accounted  for 
by  variations  in  the  magnitude  of  dividends  distributed. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  79 

When  the  figures  on  the  undistributed -profits  tax  are  broken  down 
by  more  detailed  industrial  groups  these  observations  are  generally 
substantiated.  See  chart  XX,  which  presents  tax  data  for  86  in- 
dustries. From  this  chart  it  is  readily  apparent  that  there  w^ere  very 
substantial  industrial  differences  in  the  operation  of  the  undistributed- 
profits  tax,  the  tax-profits  ratio  ranging  from  a  high  of  4.9  percent  for 
agricultural  machinery  to  0.1  percent  for  telephone  and  telegraph. 
The  ratio  of  the  former  was  49  times  as  high  as  the  ratio  of  the  latter. 

The  fact  that  certain  exceptions  (i.  e.,  radios,  shipbuilding,  motion- 
picture  producers)  appear  to  the  general  observation  can  be  explained 
in  terms  of  the  behavior  of  individual  corporations  within  the  industry. 
The  main  tendency  is  clearly  shown.  It  is  interesting  to  observe  that 
the  upper  part  of  the  chart — where  the  tax  ratios  are  high  and  the 
distribution  of  profits  is  relatively  low — are  to  be  found  the  industries 
known  to  be  largely  small  scale  and  highly  competitive — while  the 
lower  part  of  the  chart — where  the  tax  rates  are  low  and  the  dis- 
tribution-of-dividends  rates  are  high — are  to  be  found  industries 
characteristically  organized  on  large  scale  and  commonly  cited  as 
^'monopolistic." 


CHAPTER  VI 

FEDERAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAXES  PAID  BY 
CORPORATIONS  OF  VARYING  SIZE,  1931-37 

This  concluding  section  of  the  size  chapters  is  designed  to  indicate 
the  aggregate  effect  of  Federal  taxes  upon  corporate  profits  in  various 
size  and  industrial  classes,  insofar  as  available  data  permit.  Each 
type  of  Federal  corporate  incorp.e  tax — the  normal  income  tax,  the 
capital  stock,  and  excess-profits  taxes,  and  the  undistributed  profits 
tax — has  been  separatel^^  examined  in  detail  in  this  and  the  three  fore- 
going chapters.  To  what  extent  have  Federal  corporate  incon\e  taxes 
reduced  corporate  incom.e  that  would  otherwise  be  available  for  (a) 
distribution  of  dividends  to  stockholders  (inaividual  and  corporate) 
and  (6)  reinvestment  (and  industrial  replacem.ent)  by  corporations  of 
varying  size  and  industrial  classes? 

Available  data  are  unfortunately  not  sufficient  to  furnish  a  com.plete 
answer  to  this  inquiry  at  the  present  tim.e.  But  the  deficiencies  in  the 
data  are  hardly  of  such  a  m.agnitude  as  to  preclude  any  comparisons 
at  all.  One  deficiency  is  the  lack  of  data  on  the  operation  of  the 
Federal  capital-stock  tax  and  the  other  is  the  im.possibility  of  corre- 
lating the  undistributed  profits  tax  of  the  corporation  and  the  income- 
tax  pajmients  of  the  individual  stockholders  on  dividends.  The 
omission  of  the  capital-stock  tax  is  not  believed,  in  view  of  the  analysis 
presented  in  section  1  of  the  preceding  chapter,  to  introduce  any  sub- 
stantial bias  into  the  size  and  industrial  com.parisons.  Data  on  the 
undistributed  profits  tax  are  presented  always  in  conjunction  with 
data  on  distributed  dividends. 

The  statistical  answer  to  the  inquiry  will  be  sought  in  term.s  of  three 
different  charts:  (a)  In  actual  dolla.rs  (for  4  size  groups  during  a 
7-year  period  (1931-37)),  (b)  in  percents  of  corporate  profits  for 
10  size  groups  crossed  by  22  industrial  groups  in  1937,  and  (c)  in 
percents  of  corporate  profits  for  91  minor  industrial  groups  in  1937. 
For  the  purpose  of  the  first  chart  it  was  found  advisable  to  reclassif}^ 
the  corporations  into  4  asset-size  classes — sm.all  (with  assets  under 
$250,000),  m.edium -sized  (assets  from.  $250,000  to  $5,000,000),  large 
(assets  from.  5  to  50  million  dollars),  and  giants  (assets  $50,000,000) 
while  the  regular  10  asset-size  classes  are  retained  in  the  second  com.- 
parison.  The  third  comparison  involves  no  size  com.parisons  but 
presents  greater  industrial  detail.  ''Corporate  profits"  are  through- 
out defined  in  term.s  of  ''compiled  net  profits"  (of  Statistics  of  Incom.e), 
including  intercorporate  dividends  and  interest  received  from,  tax- 
exempt  securities,  both  of  which  are  at  the  disposal  of  the  receiving 
corporation.  These  charts  cannot  be  used  to  show  the  relative  "tax 
burden"  ^  of  corporations  of  different  size  classes  without  considering 
the  taxable  status  of  intercorporate  dividends  and  interest  from,  govern- 
mental securities  that  were  examined  at  length  in  the  preceding 
chapter. 

1  It  may  be  questioned  whether  it  is  possible  to  speak  of  the  "tax  burden"  of  other  than  natural  persons. 

81 


32  OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Chart  XXII  shows  for  the  four  size  groups  for  each  year  (repre- 
sented by  a  smgle  bar),  between  1931  and  1937,  the  magnitudes  (in 
millions  of  dollars)  of  (a)  Federal  corporation  income  taxes  (at  top  of 
the  chart),  (6)  corporate  profits  after  taxes  that  were  distributed  to 
stockholders  as  cash  dividends  (second  section  of  the  bar  from  the 
top),  (c)  income  available  for  reinvestment  (third  section  of  the  bar), 
and  {(1)  funds  accrued  (income  available)  for  industrial  replacement 
(lowest  section  of  the  bar). 

In  all  size  classes  the  recovery  in  corporate  profits  has  been  substan- 
tial in  magnitude.  Each  size  class  showed  a  steady  gain  in  corporate 
profits  (before  and  after  taxes)  year-by-year  from  1932  and  1936. 
But  only  the  giant  corporations  continued  to  increase  the  volume  of 
their  profits  in  1937 ;  the  other  size  classes  reported  a  smaller  volume  of 
profits  in  1937  than  in  1936.  The  rate  of  recovery  has  been  lowest  for 
the  giant  corporations,  but  likewise  their  profits  declined  less  precipi- 
tously and  consequently  had  less  ground  to  regain. 

The  substantial  recover}^  in  corporate  profits  has  been  offset  by 
increasing  Federal  incoftie  taxes  only  to  a  minor  extent  (infra).  The 
relative  effect  of  such  taxes  upon  corporate  profits  in  the  various  size 
classes  can  be  gaged  from  a  comparison  of  the  rates  of  increase  of 
corporate  profits  before  taxes  with  the  rate  of  increase  of  profits  after 
taxes.  This  comparison  gives  probably  the  clearest  indication  of  the 
relative  role  in  recent  years  of  Federal  corporate  income  taxes  ^  in 
reducing  corporate  profits  otherwise  available  for  distribution  of 
dividends.^  Expressing  the  rate  of  increase  from  1932  to  1937  of 
corporate  profits  before  taxes  as  100  in  each  size  class,  the  rate  of 
increase  of  prohts  after  taxes  (excluding  the  undistributed  pi'ofits  tax) 
was  100  for  the  small  corporations,  99  for  the  giant  corporations,  97 
for  the  large  corporations,  and  9G  for  the  medium-sized  corporations. 
This  comparison  indicates  that  the  curtailing  effect  of  the  Federal 
corporation  income  taxes  upon  corporate  profits  was  somev/hat  greater 
in  the  medium-sized  class  of  corporations  than  in  the  case  of  either  the 
giant  or  the  small  corporations.  A  size  comparison  of  the  rate  of 
increase  of  taxes  between  1932  and  1937  likewise  shows  the  highest 
increase  occurring  in  the  medium-size  group.  The  explanation  for  this 
size  differential  is  to  be  found  in  the  one  case  (i.  e.,  small  corporations) 
in  the  graduated  feature  of  the  normal  tax  and  in  the  other  case 
(i.  e.,  giant  corporations)  in  the  operation  of  the  special  credits  for 
investment  income. 

This  chart  also  shows  the  relative  magnitude  of  corporate  funds 
available  for  reinvestment  and  industrial  replacement  (i.  e.,  corporate 
profits  after  all  taxes  and  cash  dividends  paid  out  plus  depreciation 
and  depletion)  in  the  various  size  classes.  The  rate  of  recovery  of 
such  corporate  funds  can  be  shown  by  a  comparison  of  the  same  with 
the  rate  of  recovery  of  corporate  profits  before  taxes  and  dividends. 
Holding  the  latter  constant  at  100,  the  rate  of  recovery  between  1932 
and  1937  of  corporate  investment  replacement  funds  was  68  for  the 
small  corporations,  73  for  the  medium-sized  corporations,  and  87  for 
the  large  and  giant  corporations. 

''  In  this  partionlar  comparison,  thp  undistributed  profits  tax  has  been  omitted. 

-  The  years  1931-33  are  not  entirely  comparable  with  one  another,  nor  with  the  succeeding  period  as  a 
result  of  statutorj'  changes  with  respect  to  the  filing  of  consolidated  income-tax  returns. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XXII 


83 


MILLIONS  or 

""km 


BULLIONS  OF 
OOLLAaS 

4,000 


3.-000 


2,500 


3,500 


3.0C0 


2,500 


Small  Corporations      Medium-Si zeo 
(Assets  Uhoer  Corporations 


$50,000) 


LEGEND 


(Assets 

1250,00 


ET8  From 

000  TC 
000) 


Large  Corporations  Giant  Corporations 

(Assets  Frow  (Assets  Over 

55.000,000  TO  $50,000,000) 

$56,000,000) 


"§DERAL  CGRPORATIOM   INCOME  TAXES  (INCLUDING  EXCESS^P?0FITS 
Tax  SINtlE  1333  AND  UNDISTRIBUTED  PROFITS  TAX   IN   h3^31) 

DORFORATE  INCOf^'E  PA  10  OUT  AS  CASi  D!VIDE:>iDS 

{CORPORATE   INCaiE  AFTER  TAXES  AND  D!ViOE^aS  ^  £> '40-J36 

^^DEPRECIATION  AND  DEPLETION  CHARGES 


Source:  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 
Department  of  Commerce. 


34  CONOENTRATION  OF  E(:0N0:MIC  POWER 

These  general  size  patterns  have  been  broken  down  by  22  industries 
for  1937  in  chart  XXIII.  In  order  to  make  comparisons  easier,  com- 
piled net  profits  (including  intercorporate  dividends  and  interest  from 
governmental  securities)  are  expressed  as  100,  rather  than  in  absolute 
dollars,  and  the  three  types  of  taxes  (i.  e.,  the  normal  tax,  the  excess- 
profits,  and  the  imdistributed-profits  tax),  cash  dividends  paid  out, 
and  residual  profi.ts  (i.  e.,  after  taxes  and  dividends)  are  shown  as 
percentages  of  corporate  profits  before  Federal  income  taxes. "^  The 
normal  tax  is  shown  at  the  top  of  the  chart.  Next  follows  the  excess- 
profits  tax.  Both  of  these  taxes  are  collected  by  the  Federal  Govern- 
ment irrespective  of  corporate  policies  as  to  the  (listribution  of  cash 
dividends,  the  relative  magnitude  of  which  is  shown  next.  The  un- 
distributed-profits tax,  which  is  a  function  of  the  magnitude  of  divi- 
dends paid  out,  is  shown  below  cash  dividends.  The  residual  area 
indicates  the  percentage  of  corporate  profits  remaining  after  all  taxes 
and  cash  dividends — that  is,  income  available  for  reinvestment  or  as 
liquid  reserves.  It  was  unfortunately  not  technically  feasible  to  show 
on  this  diagram  the  relative  magnitude  of  depreciation  and  depletion 
which  are  frequently  the  source  of  corporate  expansion  as  well  as 
replacement.  The  investment  area  was  affected  by  the  undistributed- 
profits  tax  in  at  least  two  ways — (a)  by  forcing  distribution  of  divi- 
dends in  order  to  avoid  payment  of  the  surtax  and  (b)  by  reducing 
income  after  taxes  and  dividends  by  the  amount  of  the  surtax  legally 
due  (i.  e.,  from  7  to  27  percent  of  the  residual,  less  credits  for  tax- 
exempt  interest). 

These  charts  clearly  show  that  Federal  corporate  income  taxes  in 
the  aggregate  (i.  e.,  the  normal  tax  plus  the  excess-profi.ts  tax  plus  the 
undistributed-profits  tax)  reduced  corporate  profits  otherwise  dispos- 
able to  the  greatest  extent  in  the  medium-sized  classes.  This  state- 
ment does  not  take  into  account  the  role  of  individual  stockholders 
whose  tax  payments  of  course  depend  upon  the  distribution  policy  of 
the  corporation.  It  is  applicable  to  all  major  industries  except  finance 
where  the  curtailing  effect  of  taxes  w^as  greatest  in  the  smaller-size 
classes.  Corporate  profits  were  reduced  to  the  least  extent  by  Federal 
corporate  income  taxes  in  the  largest-size  classes,  except  trade,  where 
the  effect  of  taxes  was  least  in  the  smaller-size  classes. 

The  magnitude  of  corporate  profits  remaining  after  taxes  and  divi- 
dends varied  inversely  with  corporate  size — that  is,  the  amount  of 
profits  retained  for  investment  purposes  or  as  liquid  reserves  was 
relatively  greater  in  the  smaller  corporations  than  in  the  medium-sized 
and  large  corporations,  and,  conversely,  the  amount  of  retained  profits 
was  relatively  smaller  in  the  large  corporations  than  in  the  small  and 
medium-sized  corporations.  This  observation  does  not  apply  to  (a) 
mining  ^  where  the  aggregate  amount  of  cash  dividends  paid  out  ex- 
ceedecl  total  corporate  profits  in  all  size  classes  except  the  largest  or 
(b)  finance  where  retained  profits  were  relatively  largest  in  the  medium- 
sized  classes.  The  undistributed-profits  tax  was  larger  on  the  small 
and  medium-sized  corporations,  as  has  already  been  shown,  but  did 
not  markedly  curtail  such  undistributed  profits. 

*  The  capital-stock  tax  has  been  already  deducted  as  an  expense  item.    See  sec.  1  of  this  chapter. 

5  The  fact  that  mining  corporations  as  a  group  reported  surtaxes  on  undistributed  profits,  despite  the  fact 
that  cash  dividends  exceeded  profits  in  the  aggregate,  can  be  explained  only  by  assinuing  considerable  va- 
riation among  individual  corporations— one  corporation,  for  reasons  sufficient  to  itself,  chose  to  pay  out  cash 
dividends  equivalent  to  loO  percent  of  its  profits,  while  another  corporation,  for  equally  self-sufficient 
reasons,  chose  to  pay  out  cash  dividends  only  to  the  extent  of  60  percent  of  its  profits.  The  sum  of  these 
would  show  a  surtax  and  yet  a  dividend  distribution  of  105  percent. 


Hjq  3T0U00JI9  f>3fle>i« 


01  e  8  T  a  e  ^  £  ' 


Chart  XXIII— Continued 


FEDERAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAXES   DISTRIBUTION  OF  DIVIDENDS  AND 
RETENTION  OF  PROFITS  BY  CORPORATIONS  OF  VARYING  SIZE  AND  INDUSTRIES 

(NET -INCOME  TAX  RETURNS  ONLY) 


a  UNDISTRIBUTED  PROFITS  TAX 


piiiiii  "iiiiiiir  liiiiiiir  "iiiii 


kmm  wMm.  mM  mmH  iliL  lil. 


FOREST  PRODUCTS  Pes  cm 


3456789  10 


"iifiMiir   mmmw 


P^'ROLEUM  STONE.  CLAY.  GLASS 


MOTOR  VEHICLES 


ciMiiiiiiiiiiiiii  jiiijikiililiik    l.iiiiihiriiiniiil 


[ill 

23456789  10 


lai 


lii  ill  ii 


3456789  10 


JiL    JJU 


3456789  10 


a02«»8-4 1  _  No.  9     ( Faoe  p.  85 ) 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


85 


Chart  XXIII 


FEDERAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAXES 
DISTRIBUTION  OF  DIVIDENDS  AND  RETENTION 
OF  PROFITS  BY  CORPORATIONS  OF  VARYING  SIZE 
AND  INDUSTRIES,  1937 

(net-income  tax  returns  only) 


0  Jj^iJ-A^ 


11±^^A. 


l^XAAlH. 


90 
100 


I Z  3  4  5  6' 63 
ALL  CORPORATSOHS     MANUFACTURING 

[INCWD'm  AGRIC 


MINING 


I2:i4567d0l0        /  23456739  10 

TRADE  SERVICE 


ASSCr  SIZE  CLASSES 


250,000  TO  ^, 

5!oo.,„^„ 
,000,000  TO  16,000,000 


,000  TO  5,000,000 


I23f667b3l0        123456789  10        I  23  4  56789  10 
CONS'^RUCTIOH       PUBLIC  UTILITIES  FINANCE 

DEPARTMENT   OF    CO.MSEffCE 


Over  100,000,000 


^y  Excess-profits  Tax 
FS-^  Cash  Dividends  Paid  Out 
^^  Undistributed  Profits  Tax 
V^'^  Retained  Profits 


SOURCE:  Computed  from  "Statistics  of  Income" 
AND  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical 
Section  of  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue 


202008 — 41  — No.  ".) 7 


86  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Chart  XXIV  (the  construction  of  which  parallels  chart  XXIII) 
shows  these  same  relationships  for  91  minor  industrial  groups.  The 
industries  have  been  ranked  by  the  magnitude  of  profits  remaining 
after  taxes  and  dividends.  Such  profits  were  very  substantial  for 
several  kinds  of  financial  corporations  (e.  g.,  insurance  and  banks)  and 
very  low  or  practically  nonextant  for  various  types  of  public  utilities 
(e.  g.,  gas,  light  and  power,  telephone  and  telegraph)  and  consumers^ 
goods  industries  (e.  g.,  sugar,  silk  and  rayon,  boots  and  shoes).  The 
characteristics  of  any  specific  industry  are  apparent  upon  inspection 
and  need  not  be  elaborated  further  here. 


z    — 


I 


gUi 

Ts:     o    o 

§  ^ 

-<      Ui 

UJ     >» 


CHAPTER  VII 

FEDERAL  TAXATION  OF  MONOPOLY  PROFITS:  A  NEGATIVE 

RECORD 

High  corporate  profits  in  relation  to  investment  may  result  from 
(a)  a  condition  of  ''imperfect  competition"  of  a  sort  that  may  be  loosely 
labeled  ''monopoly,"  (b)  a  return  on  investment  commensurate 
with  the  degree  of  risk  involved,  or  (c)  a  sudden  increase  in  demand 
(e.  g.,  during  war)  which  cannot  be  met  by  existing  capacity.  If  the 
accounting  period  is  sufficiently  long,  the  second  type  of  high  profits 
for  a  single  year  will  be  offset  by  losses  in  previous  or  succeeding  years. 
The  first  type  is  appropriately  termed  monopoly  profits,  while  the 
third  type  is  the  case  of  "war  profits,"  which  may  be  quite  unrelated 
to  "monopoly"  as  generally  conceived. 

The  Federal  tax  laws  have  only  once  been  directly  concerned  with 
the  degree  of  profitability  of  corporations  and  that  only  as  an  emer- 
gency program  to  finance  the  wartime  activities  of  Federal  Govern- 
ment. This  single  incident  was  the  excess-profits  tax  in  effect  between 
1917-21,  and  the  war-profits  tax  of  1918.^ 

With  the  expiration  of  the  war  excess-profits  tax  in  1921,  the  Federal 
tax  laws  reverted  to  their  earlier  emphasis  upon  the  mere  dollar 
magnitude  of  profits  to  the  exclusion  of  any  concern  with  the  rate  of 
profit  of  corporations.  If  corporations  have  a  net  income  a  Federal 
tax  was  imposed  at  a  fixed  rate  irrespective  of  the  relationship  of 
such  income  to  investment.  The  enactment  of  the  excess-profits  tax 
in  1933  changed  this  situation  only  in  a  minor  respect.  That  tax  was 
no  attack  via  taxation  upon  the  high  profits  of  corporations,  but  did 
discriminate  against  corporations  with  fluctuating  income.^  Fluc- 
tuating income  implies  high  and  low  points  of  profit.  Whenever  the 
high  point  was  reached  without  accurate  anticipation  by  the  corpora- 
tion (i.  e.,  in  its  capital-stock  declaration),  it  found  itself  subject  to  an 
excess-profits  tax. 

The  definition  of  taxable  net  income  for  Federal  tax  purposes  may 
indirectly  involve  some  tax  discrimination  among  corporations  accord- 
ing to  their  rates  of  profits.  For  example,  high  profits  are  more  likely 
to  result  in  the  case  of  operating  companies  than  in  the  case  of  cor- 
porations deriving  most  of  their  income  from  investment  sources 
(i.  e.,  intercorporate  dividends  and  Government  interest),  which  are 
substantially  exempt  from  Federal  taxation  in  the  hands  of  the 
recipient  corporation.  To  this  extent  only  can  it  be  said  that  the 
present  Federal  corporate  income  taxes  attack  "high  corporate  profits." 

The  actual  tax  experience  of  corporations  of  varying  profitability 
during  a  recent  4-year  period  (1934-37)  is  shown  in  chart  XXV,  which 
is  based  on  profits  and  investment  figures  filed  by  435  manufacturing 

1  See  appendix  A  for  a  brief  review  of  wartime  taxation.    The  excess  profits  tax  enacted  by  the  Second 
Revenue  Act  of  1940  constitutes  another  potential  exception  to  the  statement  in  the  text. 
*  Supra,  pp.  69-70. 

87 


gg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

corporations  with  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission  and  on  the 
tax  data  reported  by  the  identical  group  to  the  Department  of  Com- 
merce. These  corporations  have  been  grouped  into  9  profit  classes, 
based  on  the  ratio  of  ''net  before  interest"  to  ''invested  capital" 
(including  long-term  debt).^  The  Federal  normal  corporate-income 
and  excess-profits  taxes  and  the  capital-stock  tax  are  measured  as  a 
percent  of  "net."  From  this  diagram  it  is  readily  apparent  that,  in 
each  year  between  1934  and  1937,  the  relative  magnitude  of  such 
Federal  taxes  tended  to  vary  somewhat  with  the  rate  of  corporate 
profits.  That  is,  the  tax-profits  ratio  was  higher  on  the  more  profitable 
corporations  and  lower  on  the  less  profitable  corporations.  This 
direct  relationship  between  the  relative  magnitude  of  the  tax  and  the 
profit  rate,  however,  was  not  invariably  in  evidence,  although  these 
exceptions  to  the  general  pattern  may  be  the  consequence  of  extreme 
cases,  nor  was  it  very  substantially  in  magnitude.  Standing  by 
itself,  the  capital  stock  tax  was  clearly  larger  on  the  less  profitable 
corporations,  as  may  be  expected  in  view  of  the  analysis  presented 
in  the  preceding  chapter. 

These  tendencies  are  substantially  confirmed  when  the  figures  are 
broken  down  by  size  and  industries  for  1937.  The  size  variations  for 
1937  are  shown  as  the  lower  part  of  chart  XXV,  while  the  industrial 
variations  in  1937  are  shown  in  chart  XXVI  (based  on  578  corpora- 
tions). In  most  cases  the  tax-profits  ratios  were  highest  in  the  most 
profitable  groups,  while  in  other  cases  the  reverse  relationship  was 
noticeable. 

These  data  show  a  slight  tendency  for  the  Federal  corporate  income, 
excess-profits,  and  captal-stock  taxes  (in  the  aggregate)  to  vary  with 
corporate  profitability.  It  is  difficult  to  reach  very  definite  conclu- 
sions, however,  as  to  whether  and  to  what  degree  existing  Federal 
income  taxes  curtail  corporate  profits  differently  in  various  profitability 
groups. 

One  of  the  justifications  made  of  the  undistributed-profits  tax 
by  its  proponents  was  its  effect  in  curbing  "monopoly."  As  originally 
enacted  in  the  1936  Revenue  Act,  however,  the  undistributed-profits 
tax  approached  this  problem  only  indirectly  and  without  adequate 
differentiation  between  industries  with  fluctuating  income  and  those 
with  stable  income. 

The  approach  of  the  undistributed-profits  tax  to  the  m.onopoly 
problem,  was  indirect  because  it  focused  on  that  portion  of  corporate 
profits  which  rem.ained  undustributed  and  was  not  directly  concerned 
with  the  relationship  of  profits  to  investment.  Yet  it  is  known  that 
the  amount  of  profits  retained  after  the  paym.ent  of  dividends  tends  to 
vary  directly  with  the  rate  of  profit — that  is,  the  m,ore  profitable 
corporations  tend  to  distribute  relatively  less  of  their  profits  or  divi- 
dends than  do  the  less  profitable  corporations.  Eegular  payment  of 
dividends  are,  of  course,  essential  to  the  maintenance  of  corporate 
reputations  upon  the  capital  m.arket  and  hence  are  apt  to  vary  rela- 
tively less  over  tim,e  than  the  volume  of  profits  retained  within  the 
corporate  system..  By  im.posing  a  special  tax  upon  the  latter  it  is 
clear  the  m.ost  profitable  corporations  are  apt  to  pay  a  larger  tax  of 
this  sort  than  the  less  profitable  corporations. 

3  For  definition  of  terms,  see  Technical  Appendix  E.    Note  that  the  data  used  in  this  chapter  have  not 
been  compiled  on  a  basis  entirely  comparable  to  that  of  the  data  presented  in  the  previous  chapter. 


Chabt  XXV 

FEDERAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAX  PAYMENTS  AS  PER  CENT 

OF  NET  PROFIT  BEFORE  INTEREST 

435  MANUFACTURING  CORPORATIONS 

BY  PROFIT  RATE  CLASSES 

1934-1937 


UNOISTRteuTED  PROFITS  TAX 

CAPITAL  STOCK  TAX 

NORMAL  S  EXCESS  PROFITS  TA 


PROFIT    RATE    CLASSES 

( NET  AS  PER  CENT  OF  INVESTED  CAPITAL  ) 
UNDER  5  6-29-30 


10-15  805-40 

15-20  9.  OVER  40 

20 -Z5 


AVERAGE   1934-1937 


3      4      5      6 


2      3      4      5      6       7 


BY  SIZE, 1937 

2  3 

(jipoopoo-$5,ooopoo)  ($5,000j000-»l0p00,000)  ($IOpOO,000 


$200p00p001  lOVER  $200.000.0001 


123456789        123456769        123 

Source:  Department  of  Commerce  Survey  of  Business  Taxation. 


S— il— No.  9     (Face  p. 


(       Ui/.K<..» 


M3ivvvM  i  aAT  3M00HI  3TA?10q?100  JAH3a31 
fl3Tl/ll  3H033a  TRO^iq  T3M  30 
DITAROSROO  OI/imUTOAlUHAM  a£^ 
8338AJ0  3TAFI  TRO^q  YG 


FP\    irNAP"^VA 


>y:-^ 


T£ei.3 


9 


Chart  XXVI 

FEDERAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAX  PAYMENTS  AS  PER  CENT 

OF  NET  PROFIT  BEFORE  INTEREST 

578  LARGE  MANUFACTURING  AND  TRADE  CORPORATIONS 

BY  PROFIT  RATE  CLASSES 

1937 


B  CAPITAL   STOCK  TAX 
NORMAL  &  EIXCESS  PROFITS  TAX 


PROFIT 

(NET  AS  PER 

RATE    CLASSES    11 

CENT  OF  INVESTED  CAPIT4L)      || 

1  ■ UNDER  5 
2.  5-10 
3.10-15 

4.15-20 
5.20-25 
S. 25-30 

7-30-35 
8.35-40 
9.0VEH40 

3    15    6     7 

CHEMICALS 


2    3    4     5    6     7    ( 

PETROLEUM 


123456769 

BUILDING  PRODUCTS      % 


IRON  &  STEEL 


CHAIN  STORES 


».     DEPARTMENT  STORES 


IISCELLANEOUS 


;  Survey  of  Business  Taxation. 


202698— 41— No.  0      (Face  p.  88)      No.  2 


i'VIYAS  XAT  3M00H!  BTA^CSFIOO  JAnSQBl 
^"'"\  3^10138  mom  T3H  30 
.  -AflT  QUA  OHmUTOAlUMAM  BORA     '^  — 
;53aAJ0  BTAFi  TllOfiq  Ya 
Tcei 


fl3HT^ 


R^-  !i  L2  P^  ifi  ^> 


Ifal 


\    8   a   ^ 


^U 


iL&SH-K^L, , 


" 

i 


wo 


0)3   ■■  ■ 
-I  ^ 


Uj5    °; 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


89 


If  one  of  the  purposes  of  such  a  tax  is  to  check  imperfect  competi- 
tion, however,  it  is  necessary  that  the  tax  discriminate  between  the 
two  types  of  profit  situations  outhned  by  extending  the  accounting 
period  or  by  permitting  the  carry-over  of  losses.  The  surtax  provi- 
sions of  the  1936  Revenue  Act  permitted  only  the  carry-over  of 
excess  credits  for  dividends  paid  out,  while  the  revision  of  the  tax 
by  the  1938  Revenue  Act  expressly  provided  for  a  loss  carry-over  for 
the  previous  year.^ 

Chart  XXY  shows  the  relative  m.agnitude  of  the  undistributed- 
profits  tax  in  1936-37  for  435  m.anufacturing  corporations  classified 
by  9  profit  classes  and  by  6  size  classes  (in  the  lower  part  of  the  dia- 
gram). Both  in  1936  and  in  1937  the  relative  m.agnitude  of  the 
undistributed-profits  tax  tended  to  vary  with  the  profit  rate — that  is, 
the  undistributed-profits  tax  ratio  was  relatively  larger  in  the  case 
of  the  more  profitable  corporations  and  relatively  lower  in  the  case  of 
the  less  profitable  group.  When  these  figures  are  broken  down  by 
size  classes  it  is  discovered  that  this  tendency  is  very  m.arked  in  the 
middle  size  classes  (assets  from  1  to  50  million) — which  probably 
include  the  so-called  growing  corporations — while  no  tendency  (or  in 
fact  a  contrar}^  tendency  in  the  case  of  the  giants)  is  noticeable  in 
the  larger  size  classes.  This  size  disparity  can  perhaps  be  explained 
by  the  easy  access  of  the  larger  corporation  to  the  capital  m.arket. 
The  latter  group,  to  this  extent,  forms  an  exception  to  the  general 
observation  on  the  direct  relationship  between  the  proportion  of 
profits  retained  within  the  corporation  and  the  rate  of  profit.  Inso- 
far as  ''monopoly"  or  ° 'imperfect  com.petition"  can  be  associated 
with  large  corporations,  it  should  be  apparent  that  the  undistributed- 
profits  tax  contributes  little  to  the  solution  of  the  m.onopoly  problem, 
since  the  ready  access  of  such  corporations  to  the  capital  m.arket 
obviates  reliance  on  retained  profits  as  a  technique  of  growth.  In 
the  case  of  the  gi-owing  or  m.iddle-sized  corporations  Avhich  m.ay  not 
possess  easy  access  to  the  capital  m.arket  and  therefore  distribute 
less  profits,  it  is  not  unlikely  that  an  undistributed-profits  tax  m.ay 
operate  to  check  "m.onopolistic  tendencies."  In  a  word,  an  undis- 
tributed-profits tax  may  not  curb  existing  m.onopolies  but  m.ay 
constitute  a  check  to  the  growth  of  new  m.onopolies. 

Chart  XXVII  shows  the  m.agnitude  of  the  undistributed-profits  tax 
in  1937  for  578  corporations,  classified  by  9  profit  classes  and  21  indus- 
tries. The  direct  relationship  between  the  m.agnitude  of  the  tax  and 
the  rate  of  profit  is  readily  apparent  in  beverages,  tobacco,  textiles, 
rubber,  building  products,  iron  and  steel,  m.achinery,  and  chain  stores. 
In  chemicals,  transportation  equipm.ent,  and  departm.ent  stores  a 
reverse  tendency  m.ust  be  noted  while  in  the  rem.aining  industries  no 
tendency  is  observable. 

The  four  Federal  taxes  based  on  or  related  to  corporate  profits  in  the 
aggregate  tend  to  vary  roughly  with  the  rate  of  corporate  profits  in 
relation  to  investment — that  is,  the  tax-profits  ratio  tends  to  be  higher 
on  the  m.ore  profitable  corporations  than  on  the  less  profitable.  Yet  it 
should  be  obvious  that  the  tax  variation  is  neither  large  nor  universally 
in  evidence,  while  the  variation  in  profits  is  very  considerable.  Out  of 
the  591  corporations  in  the  1937  tax  sample,  m.ore  than  one-third  of  the 
num.ber  of  corporations,  reporting  approxim.-ately  half  of  the  incom.e  of 

*  See  Internal  Revenue  Code,  sec.  26  (c). 


90 


OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


the  group,  reported  profits  of  more  than  15  percent  on  investment. 
(See  fcable  VIII.)  It  is  obvious  that  the  Federal  taxes  affect  ' 'mo- 
nopoly" profits  only  to  a  very  minor  extent. 

Table  VIII. — Numher  of  corporations  and  amount  of  net  before  interest  of  591 
manufacturing  and  trade  corporations  in  1937  tax  sample,  hy  profit  rate  classes 


Number  of  corporations 

Net  before  interest 

Profit  rate  classes 

Actual 
number 

Percent 

Cumula- 
tive 
percent 

Actual 
amount 
(million) 

Percent 

Cumula- 
tive 
(percent) 

Deficit                                    -.- 

13 
62 

167 
128 
80 
59 
39 
25 
12 
6 

2.2 

10.5 

28.2 

21.7 

13.5 

10.0 

8.6 

4.2 

2.0 

1.0 

99.9 

97.7 

87.2 

69.0 

37.3 

23.8 

13.8 

7.2 

3.0 

1.0 

0) 

43 

718 

549 

475 

325 

182 

79 

11 

11 

Under  5 

l.S 

30.0 

22.9 

19.9 

13.6 

7.6 

3.3 

.4 

.5 

100.0 

5  to  10...             

98.2 

10  to  15 

68.2 

I5to20 .       

45.3 

20  to  25 

25.4 

25  to  30 

11.8 

30  to  35 

4.2 

35  to  40 

.9 

Over  40 

.5 

Total                          

591 

100.  0 

2,392 

1  Denotes  red  figure. 

Note.— Profit  rate  equals  net  before  interest  as  percent  of  inverted  capital  (including  long-term  debt). 


i 


CHAPTER  VIII 

EQUITY  VERSUS  CREDITOR  CAPITAL  IN  FEDERAL 
CORPORATE  INCOME  TAXATION 

Corporate  activities  maj^  be  financed  by  stockholders  or  by  bond- 
holders, or  by  both,  or,  after  the  corporation  has  been  operating  for  a 
time,  b}^  undistributed  profits  and  depreciation.^  The  contribution  of 
the  stockholders  is  conventionally  termed  "equity"  capital — other 
term,s  are  ''risk"  or  'Venture"  capital — -while  that  of  the  bondholders 
is  called  debt  or  "creditor"  capital.  These  different  m.odes  of  cor- 
porate financing  have  particular  advantages  over  one  another.  If  any 
general  statement  can  be  m.ade,  it  can  probably  be  said  that  financing 
by  "risk"  capital  is  probably  preferable  to  creditor  financing.  It  is 
at  any  rate  clear  that  the  converse  proposition  can  be  sustained  only 
with  great  difficulty  and  subject  to  several  limitations.^ 

The  Federal  tax  laws,  however,  at  present  discriminate  in  favor  of 
creditor  financing  by  exem.ptmg  from  the  corporation's  tax  base  all  pay- 
ments of  interest  to  bondholders,  while  of  course  no  deduction  is 
allowed  for  dividends  paid  out  to  stockholders  (except  in  the  case  of 
the  surtax  on  undistributed  profits).  Such  interest  is  of  course  tax- 
able in  the  hands  of  the  recipient  (i.  e.,  the  bondholders),  but  so  are 
dividends  received  by  natural  persons.  Insofar  as  corporate  capital — 
whether  equity  or  debt — is  contributed  by  other  corporations,  the  tax 
discrimination  is  not  so  marked  since  (a)  in  the  case  of  equity  capital 
the  earning  corporation  paj^s  the  tax  vvdiile  the  dividend-receiving 
corporation  is  substantially  exem.pt  (85  percent)  from  Federal  tax 
upon  such  dividends  and  (b)  in  the  case  of  creditor  capital  the  earn- 
ing corporation  is  free  of  taxation  upon  all  distributions  (as  interest) 
while  the  interest-receiving  corporation  is  presumably  taxed  thereon. 
From  the  point  of  view  of  the  paying  corporation  per  se,  separate 
and  apart  from  its  owners  and  creditois,  there  is  a  substantial  tax 
discrimination,  irrespective  of  the  corporate  character  of  the  contrib- 
utors of  capital.  In  the  one  case  a  distribution  in  the  form  of  interest 
is  tax-exem,pt  while  in  the  other  a  distribution  in  the  form  of  dividends 
is  taxable.^ 

The  present  statutory  deduction  for  interest  is  fairly  unlimited  in 
scope — all  interest  m.ay  be  charged  as  expense  except  that  paid  on 
indebtedness  incurred  to  acquire  tax-exem.pt  securities.  This  was  not 
the  case  prior  to  1918,  when  the  amount  of  interest  deductible  under 
the  Federal  corporate-income  tax  was  lim.ited  to  that  paid  on  indebted- 
ness which  bore  a  specified  relationship  to  equity  capital.  As  a  matter 
of  fact,  the  question  whether  any  deduction  at  all  should  be  allowed 

1  The  relation  of  Federal  taxation  to  undistributed  profits  and  depreciation  has  been  examined  in  pre- 
ceding chapters,  especially  at  pp.  17-18,  30-31,  70-79. 

2  See  Jerome  Frank,  "Too  Much  Interest  in  Interest." 

3  The  varying  importance  of  the  interest  deduction  in  diiTerent  industries  (particularly  public  utilities, 
service,  and  finance)  has  already  been  set  forth,  supra,  pp.  30-31,  70-79. 

91 


92  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

for  interest  paid  on  bonds  was  quite  warmly  debated  at  the  time  of 
the  enactm.ent  of  the  corporate  excise  tax  in  1909.  As  the  Blakeys 
report  in  their  tax  history — 

Most  of  the  Members  were  at  first  opposed  to  such  deduction  because  they 
thought  it  would  encourage  the  substitution  of  bonds  for  stocks  so  as  to  avoid 
the  tax.  Some  questioned  the  legaKty  of  taxing  earnings  set  aside  for  interest 
payment;  others  argued  that  a  tax  upon  such  funds  was  really  a  tax  upon  stock- 
holders, inasmuch  as  their  dividends  would  be  reduced  by  the  amount  deducted 
from  earnings  for  this  purpose.  Root  insisted  that  at  least  part  of  the  interest 
should  be  taxed.  One  Member  cited  a  Supreme  Court  decision  in  which  it  was 
held  that  net  earnings  included  interest  upon  bonded  indebtedness.  The  final 
decision,  a  victory  for  Root,  was  to  permit  corporations  to  deduct  interest  on  an 
amount  of  bonds  not  in  excess  of  paid-up  capital  stock.* 

The  income-tax  law  of  1913  amplified  the  scope  of  the  deduction 
by  providing  that  the  indebtedness  upon  which  the  claimed  interest 
was  paid  could  equal  (but  not  exceed)  ''one-half  of  the  sum  of  its 
interfest-bearing  indebtedness  and  its  paid-up  capital  stock  outstanding 
at  the  close  of  the  year."  ^  This  limitation  was  further  relaxed  by 
the  Revenue  Act  of  1916  which  provided  that  there  may  be  deducted 
interest  wherever  the  indebtedness  on  which  such  interest  was  paid 
equaled  or  was  less  than  ''the  sum  of  (a)  the  entire  amount  of  the 
paid-up  capital  stock  *  *  *  ^j^^i  Qry^  one-half  of  its  interest- 
bearing  indebtedness  then  outstanding."  ^  A  proviso  prohibited  the 
inclusion  in  the  interest  deduction  of  taxes  paid  on  tax-free  guaranty 
bonds.  Since  1918,  when  the  revenue  act  removed  all  restrictions 
upon  the  deductibility  of  interest,  corporations  can  deduct  "all  interest 
paid  or  accrued  within  the  taxable  year  on  indebtedness  *  *  *."  ^ 
The  1932  act  excluded  interest  paid  on  debt  incurred  to  purchase 
annuities,  which  provision  was  subsequently  repealed  by  the  1934  act. 

The  actual  tax  experience  of  435  manufacturing  corporations  of 
varying  equity  composition  of  capital  is  given  for  a  recent  4-year 
period  (1934-37)  in  chart  XXVIII.  The  corporations  have  been 
grouped  into  seven  equity  classes  based  on  the  ratio  of  equity  capital 
(i.  e.,  tangible  net  worth)  to  creditor  capital.^  Chart  XXIX  presents 
for  1937  similar  data  for  609  corporations  arranged  by  21  industries. 
The  relative  magnitude  of  the  Federal  corporate  income  taxes  (meas- 
ured as  percents  of  "net  before  interest")  shows  a  tendency  to  vary 
directly  with  the  proportion  of  equity  capital,  although  this  variation 
follows  by  no  means  a  step-by-step  pattern.  The  tax  ratios  in  the  low 
equity  classes  are  invariably  lower  than  the  tax  ratios  in  the  higher 
equity  classes,  but  the  former  does  not  invariably  furnish  the  lowest 
tax  ratios  (except  in  the  smallest  size  classes).  The  tax  differential 
arising  from  the  exemption  of  interest  paid  is  important  in  oft'setting 
corporations  with  proportionably  small  equity  capital  from  those 
having  relatively  larger  equity  capital.  But  as  the  proportion  of 
creditor  capital  diminishes  and  the  equity  ratio  arises  correspondingly 
the  tax-ratio  differentials  substantially  disappear.  Corporations  hav- 
ing substantial  equity  capital  do  not  report  lower  tax  ratios  than  cor- 
porations the  capital  of  which  is  almost  exclusively  composed  of 
equity. 

4  R.  G.  Blakcy  and  G.  C.  Blakey,  The  Federal  Income  Tax  (1940),  pp.  46-47. 
«  Sec.  n  (g)  (b). 
6  Sec.  12(a)  (3d). 
'Sec.  214  (a)  (2). 

8  For  definitions,  see  Technical  Appendix  E.    It  is  unfortunate  that  these  ax  data  do  not  include  public 
utilities,  where  creditor  financing  is  very  predominant. 


I 


I- 
z 

UJ 

o 

a: 

UJ 
Q. 

(/) 
zcr 

UJliJ 


ujCQ 

ii 

Q-U. 

5° 


CO 

z 
o 

<  UJ 

O  CO 

Q-< 

is 

cncn 

§8 

iuj 

<>- 

m 
ro 


< 

i 

III 

1 

til   IS! 

I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XXIX 


93 


FEDERAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAX  PAYMENTS  AS 
PER  CENT  OF  NET  PROFIT  BEFORE  INTEREST 

609  LARGE  MANUFACTURING  AND  TRADE  CORPORATIONS 

BY  EQUITY    RATIO  CLASSES 

1937 


CAPITAL  STOCK  TAX 


NORMAL  a  EXCESS  PROFITS  TAX 


EQUITY    RATIO   CL.ASSES 

(NET  WORTH  AS  PER  CENT  OF  TOTAL   DE8T) 

1  =  UNDER  2  5  =  :2-IG 

2  =  2-4  6  =  16-20 
3=4-8  7  =  OVER  20 
4=8-12 


LUMBER         PER  CENT 


2    3    4    5    6    7 
CHEMICALS 


2    3    4    5    6    7 


2    3    4    5    S 
LEATHER 


2    3    4    5    6    7 

RUBBER 


2    3    4     5    6     7 


BUILDING  PRODUCTS 


I  2  3  4  5  6  7 

IRON  a  STEEL 


2  3  4  5  6  7 

NONFERROUS 
METALS 


2    3    4    5    6    7 


MACHINERY 


I     2    3    4    5    6    7 
rRANSPORTATlON 


2    3    4    5    6    7 


2    3    4    5    6     7 


MISCELLANEOUS 
MANUFACTURING 


2    3    4     5    6    7 
WHOLESALE 


2    3    4    5    6    7 


2    3    4    5    6    7 


TOTAL 
MANUFACTURING 


2    3    4    5    6    7 


MISCELLANEOUS 
MERCHANDISING 


2    3    4    5    6    7 


2    3    4    5    5 


CHAIN  STORES 


■234557 


DEPARTMENT 
STORES 


Source:  Department  of  Commerce  Survey  of  Business  Taxation. 


94 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XXX 


FEDERAL  UNDISTRIBUTED  PROFITS  TAX  PAYMENTS  AS  PERCENT  OF  NET  PROFIT 
BEFORE  INTEREST,  609  LARGE  MANUFACTURING  AND  TRADE  CORPORATIONS  BY 
EQUITY  RATIO  CLASSES,  1937 


EQUITY    RATIO   CLASSES 

(NET  WORTH  AS  PER  CENT  OF  TOTAL   DEBT  ) 

I  =  UNDER  2  5 '12- 16 

2'2-4  6'l6-20 

3  •  4  -  8  7  '  OVER  20 
4«e-l2 


PER  CENT            FOOD 

BEVERAGES 

TOBACCO 

TEXTILES 

-15 
10 

5 

LUMBER       P 

■ 

Yn"'"' 

■ 

n     *■■      —           ' 

■  „ 

1. 

1     2    3    4    5    6    7 
CHEMICALS 

1.1 

1     2    3    4    5    6    7 

PETROLEUM 

1     1 

1     2    3    4     5    6    7 

LEATHER 

12     3    4     5    6    7 
X                 PAPER 

12    3    4    5    6    7 

PRINTING 

% 

1 

B 

„  Iflll    - 

Ijn  1 

t     2    3    4     5    6     7 

BUILDING  PRODUCTS 

!     2    3    4    5    6     7 

IRON  6  STEEL 

-■■      - 

12    3    4     5    6    7 

%             RUBBER 

12    3    4    5    6    7 

NONFERROUS 
METALS 

1     2    3    4    5    6    7 

MACHINERY 

% 

1 

0    -III 

12    3    4     5    6    7 

TRANSPORTATION 
%          EQUIPMENT 

■■iIIh. 

1     2    3    4    5    6     7 

MISCELLANEOUS 
MANUFACTURING 

lll.l 

12    3    4    5    6    7 

TOTAL 
MANUFACTURING 

.■-I.      . 

12    3    4    5    6    7 

CHAIN  STORES 

III..   . 

1     2    3    4    5    6    7 

DEPARTMENT 
STORES 

-0 

% 

0    -III      1 

12     3    4     5    6    7 

12    3    4     5    6    7 

%         WHOLESALE 

IIIbbh. 

1     2    3    4     5    6     7 

MISCELLANEOUS 
MERCHANDISING 

1     2    3    4    5    6    7 

TOTAL  TRADE 

JlLuJL 

12     3    4    5    6    7 

DO- ^-365- 

-0 

■  ll-l 

s  

l_l 

I     2     3    4    5    6    7 

Source:  Department  of  Commerce  Survey 


1234567  1234567 

of  Business  Taxation. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  95 

One  of  the  common  criticism.s  of  the  undistributed-profits  tax 
was  that  it  fell  with  particular  weight  on  corporations  with  consider- 
able debt.  Chart  XXVIII,  which  presents  1936-37  data  for  435 
manufacturing  corporations,  seems  to  substantiate  this  criticism, 
insofar  as  manufacturing  and  trade  corporations  are  concerned.  In 
1937  the  magnitude  of  the  undistributed  profits  tax  (measured  as 
percents  of  ''net  before  interest")  paid  by  manufacturing  corporations 
varied  inversely  (step  by  step)  with  the  extent  of  equity  capital — 
that  is,  the  highest  undistributed-profits  tax  ratios  appeared  for  those 
corporations  with  the  lowest  equity  ratios  and,  conversely,  the  lowest 
tax  ratios  appeared  for  those  corporations  with  the  highest  equity 
ratios.  When  these  general  figures  for  1937  are  broken  down  by  size  a 
similar  pattern  emerges,  except  in  the  smallest  size  classes.  This 
observation  is  largely  confirmed  by  an  industrial  comparison.  (See 
chart  XXX).  But  again  there  are  notable  exceptions  (building 
products,  paper,  transportation  equipment)  to  the  generalization  that 
the  undistributed-profits  tax  was  particularly  heavy  on  ''debt  ridden" 
corporations. 

In  1937  the  normal  tax,  excess-profits  tax,  and  capital-stock  tax  in 
the  aggregate  were  found  to  be  typically  lighter  on  those  coi-porations 
the  capital  structure  of  which  contained  a  substantial  amount  of 
debt,  while  the  undistributed  profits  tended  to  be  heavier  on  the  same 
group  of  corporations.  In  the  one  case  a  specific  part  of  the  Federal 
corporate-income  tax  system  tended  to  encourage  creditor  financing, 
while  another  specific  component  of  the  tax  system  tended  to  counter- 
act the  former  tendency.  The  net  result  in  the  various  manufacturing 
mdustries  was  a  general  tendency  for  the  tax  system  to  encourage 
creditor  financing. 


CHAPTER  IX 
VARIABLE— COST  TAXES 

An  increasing  share  of  the  revenue  of  both  the  Federal  and  State 
Governments  is  derived  from  taxes  which  vary  in  magnitude  directly 
with  the  volume  of  industrial  activity  and,  consequently,  add  to  the 
"variable  costs"  of  business  enterprise.  The  most  important  types 
of  '^  variable  cost"  taxes  are  (a)  the  pay-roll  tax  (imposed  by  the 
Federal  Government  and  by  51  other  jurisdictions),  (b)  Federal 
excise  taxes  (including  taxes  on  liquor,  tobacco,  and  various  manu- 
factured products),  and  (c)  State  sales  and  gross-receipt  taxes.  The 
actual  economic  effect  of  such  taxes  in  the  long  run  is  very  difficult  to 
determine  with  any  degree  of  precision,  since  so  many  factors  are 
involved — the  price  level,  the  competitive  situation,  labor-union 
strength,  cost  of  raw  materials,  and  the  volume  and  direction  of 
governmental  expenditures  financed  out  of  such  taxes. 

Yet  some  data  are  available  for  an  examination  of  the  extent  to 
which  such  taxes  contribute  to  the  ''costs"  of  various  tj^pes  of  busi- 
ness enterprise.  That  is  the  primary  question  which  this  chapter  pur- 
ports to  throw  some  factual  light  upon.  How  such  costs  are  ultimately 
borne  is  a  question  which  cannot  be  fully  answered  in  this  connection. 
See  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  Monograph  No.  3, 
Who  Pays  the  Taxes?  by  Gerhard  Colm  and  Helen  Tarasov. 

PAY-ROLL  TAXES 

For  the  purpose  of  financing  the  recently  enacted  social  security 
program,  the  Federal  Government  has  imposed  (a)  starting  with 
January  1,  1936,  a  special  unemployment  security  tax  at  the  rates  of 
1  percent  in  1936,  2  percent  in  1937,  and  3  percent  in  1938,  upon  the 
pay  rolls  of  enterprises  employing  eight  or  more  persons  in  all  indus- 
tries except  those  specifically  exempted  ^ — and  (b)  starting  with  1937, 
another  special  tax  (old  age)  at  1  percent  of  the  pay  rolls  of  all  enter- 
prises, irrespective  of  the  number  of  employees,  nat  specifically  exempt. 
The  first  tax  applies  to  total  pay  rolls  without  deductions  while  the 
second  tax  applies  only  to  the  first  $3,000  and  excludes  the  pay  rolls 
of  individuals  over  65.  Under  the  unemployment  security  tax  each 
employer  was  permitted  to  credit  against  the  Federal  tax  up  to  90 
percent  the  amount  paid  under  an  approved  State  unemployment 
compensation  plan.  The  purpose  of  this  tax-credit  device  was  of 
course  to  persuade  the  States  to  enact  pay-roll  taxes  for  employment 
purposes  and  was  as  such  shortly  achieved.^ 

The  impact  of  the  pay-roll  taxes  upon  business  costs  has  been 
examined  for  23,000  small  and  medium-sized  manufacturing,  trade, 

1  The  exempt  classes  initially  included  agriculture,  domestic  service,  shipping,  Government,  and  non- 
profit corporations.  ,  ,     ,    ^  ^        ^  i.     t 

2  By  June  30,  1936,  12  States  had  acted;  by  January  1,  1937,  23  additional  States  bad  acted;  and  by  June 
1937,  all  States  imposed  a  pay-roll  tax  for  unemployment. 

97 


98  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

and  service  concerns  in  1938  and  for  700  large  manufacturing'  and 
trade  corporations  in  1937.  In  the  large  sample  the  pay-roll  tax  is 
shown  for  different  size  classes  (based  on  sales)  as  percents  of  sales. 
In  the  smaller  sample  of  large  corporations  the  pay-roll  tax  is  shown 
as  percents  of  ''gross  margin"  and  the  corporations  have  been  grouped, 
in  addition  to  size  (based  on  assets)  and  industries,  by  (a)  magnitude 
of  labor  costs  and  (b)  profit  rate.^ 

Chart  XXXI  shows  the  pay-roll  tax  payments  as  percents  of  sales 
for  the  large  sample  of  23,000  concerns,  classified  into  4  size  classes 
and  12  manufacturing  industries,  11  retail  trade  groups  and  5  whole- 
sale trade  groups.  The  ratio  of  pay-roll  taxes  to  sales  tends  to  vary 
directly  with  size  in  8  out  of  36  manufacturing  industries — baking, 
dairies,  milling,  nonalcoholic  beverages,  weaving,  leather,  engines,  and 
miscellaneous  manufacturing— in  substantially  all  the  retail  groups, 
while  substantially  no  size  variations  are  apparent  in  wholesale  trade. 
Of  the  remaining  28  manufacturing  industries,  8 — meat,  distilleries, 
paper,  printing,  newspapers,  industrial  chemicals,  and  stone,  iron  and 
steel — show  an  inverse  size  relationship,  that  is,  the  pay-roll  tax  ratio 
is  lower  in  the  larger  size  classes  and  lighter  in  the  smaller  size  classes. 
In  20  industries  little  or  no  size  pattern  is  visible. 

Chart  XXXII  shows  the  pay-toll  tax  as  percent  of  ''gross  margin" 
for  700  large  manufacturing  trade  corporations  in  1937,  classified  into 
6  size  classes  (based  on  assets)  and  21  industries.  The  pay-roll  tax 
jratio  varies  directly  with  corporate  size  in  only  two  manufacturing 
industries — food  and  textiles — while  no  size  patterns  are  apparent  in 
trade.  An  inverse  relationship  between  the  pay-roll  tax  ratio  and 
corporate  size  is,  per  contra,  shown  for  beverages,  building  materials, 
nonferrous  metals,  machine  and  transportation  equipment.  In  the 
remaining  industries  no  size  patterns  are  visible. 

Whatever  variation  may  be  found  in  certain  industries  between  the 
relative  magnitude  of  pay-roll  taxes  and  the  size  of  business  enterprise 
is  a  reflection  of  at  least  three  factors — (a)  the  inapplicability  of  the 
employment  tax  to  enterprises  employing  less  than  8  persons,  (h)  the 
exemption  of  entrepreneurial  labor  from  both  pay-roll  taxes,  and  (c) 
the  exclusion  from  the  tax  base  under  the  old-age  tax  of  all  wages 
above  $3,000.  The  first  factor  is  clearly  of  importance  to  small  enter- 
prise which,  if  sufficiently  small,  is  wholly  exempt  from  taxation. 
The  second  factor  is  probably  more  important  to  small  enterprise  than 
to  middle-sized  or  large  enterprise,  since  the  labor  contribution  of  the 
entrepreneur  rapidly  diminishes  with  the  size  of  enterprise.  The 
third  factor  is  presumably  of  greater  importance  to  middle-sized  and 
large  enterprise,  since  small  enterprise  may  not  be  apt  to  employ 
many  persons  at  wages-salaries  exceeding  $3,000.  Yet  the  size  pat- 
terns are  not  very  pronounced  except  in  a  few  industries  and  in  these 
industries  the  variations  of  the  pay-roll  tax  ratio  may  be  due  to  other 
factors,  the  presence  of  which  merely  coincide  with  size  in  the  par- 
ticular instance. 

One  such  factor  is  the  relative  importance  of  labor  and  capital  to 
various  types  of  enterprises  and  is  probably  the  primary  factor  in 
producing  variations  of  the  pay-roll  tax  in  different  industries  and 
enterprises.  In  order  to  isolate  this  factor  clearly  each  corporation 
of  the  small  sample  was  classified  into  one  of  six  "labor  cost"  groups, 

2  For  definitions  and  methodology,  see  appendix  E. 


il 

CD       •^ 


5       ° 


'.^Sir^ 


I..-: 


»^<i.  '^rfP 


1% 

,^4^^^-^:^. 

-^:^^ 

fe^^ii^ 


ri^^i:r: 


^ 


i 


o     |i 

Q     I^ 

i     ^J 

"     ^ 

s  g 

1  !tj 

iiitii 

5  S^ 

S  1  ^;:,n 

fe    0^ 

(0 

0      ,^ 

H        1 

In 

g  K 

£   ti: 

55 

0(0 


I    I 


5   I 
^    a 


b 


£i^K 


8 


J 


.:^- 


f-v 


^^• 


m- 


£| 


(0  g  o 

W  3  o88c 

O  5    Zoo' 

'Ǥilli 


£8 


o 

1 


1 


I  i 


5     ° 


t 


?* 


'mm 
1 

4 
1 

1 

33 

1  ^ 

:  o 

o 

o 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XXXII 


99 


PEDERAL-STATE  PAY-ROLL  TAX  PAYMENTS  AS  PERCENT  OF  GROSS  MARGIN,  697  LARGE 
MANUFACTURING  AND  TRADE  CORPORATIONS  CLASSIFIED  BY  ASSETS  IN  MILLIONS 

1937 


libit 

I     2    3     4    5    6 


1             SIZE 

CLASSES             1 

(BASED  ON  ASSETS  IN  MILLIONS)               1 

1  - 

UNDER    1 

2  = 

1  -5 

3 

5-10 

4 

10-50 

5  = 

50-200 

6' 

OVER  200 

2    3    4    5    S 

PRINTING 


BEVERAGES 


I     2    3    4     5    6 

CHEMICALS 


TEXTILES 


LUMBER     PERCENT 

3 


Z    3    4    5    6 


RUBBER 


illtjlilCliU 


I     2    3    4    5    6 


2    3    4    5    6 

BUILDING 
PRODUCTS 


2  3  4  5  6 


IRON  &  STEEL 


2  3  4  5  6 


NONFERROUS 
METALS 


ti 


MACHINERY      x 
■ 3 


I     2    3     4    5    6 

TRANSPORTATION 
%       EQUIPMENT 

3 


ut  unit  jiiu  ]ini[ 


2    3    4    5    6 


MISCELLANEOUS 
MANUFACTURING 


2    3    4     5    6 


TOTAL 
MANUFACTURING 


2    3    4    5    6 


CHAIN  STORES 


DEPARTMENT 

STORES    % 
3 


JlUt  lUii:  Jiliit  muL  do 


2    3    4    5    6 


2    3    4    5    6 


%     .WHOLESALE 

3 


I     2    3    4     5    6 

MISCELLANEOUS 
MERCHANDISING 


2     3     4    5     6 


TOTAL  TRADE    % 


2    3    4     5    6 


lit  Tiz  mm 


123456         123456         123456 

Source:  Department  of  Commerce  Survey  of  Business  Taxation. 


ranging  from  cases  where  labor  costs  were  low  (i.  e.,  less  than  10  per- 
cent of  sales)  to  cases  where  labor  costs  were  relatively  high  (i.  e.,  more 
than  50  percent  of  sales).  The  data  are  shown  in  chart  XXXIII  for 
21  industries.  The  pay-roll  tax  ratio  to  gross  margin  varies  quite 
sharply  with  the  degree  of  labor  costs.  In  manufacturing  the  varia- 
tion in  1937  ranged  from  0.67  to  1.78  percent,  while  in  trade  the 


100 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XXXIII 


FEDERAL-STATE  PAY-EOLL  TAX  PAYMENTS  AS  PERCENT  OF  GROSS  MARGIN,  697  LARGE 
MANUFACTURING  AND  TRADE  CORPORATIONS  BY  LABOR  COST  CLASSES,  1937 


PER   CENT      FOOD 
3 


LABOR 

COST  CLASSES  1 

(PAYROLLS  AS   PER  CENT  OF  SALES)         j 

UNDER  10                                  1 

10  TO  20 

20  TO  30 

30  TO  40 

40  TO  50 

6 

OVER    50 

TOBACCO 


TEXTILES 


flt  .-t  jUt  ill  Ett 


2    3    4    5    6 


PAPER 


2     3    4    5    6 


PRINTING 


I     2    3    4    5    6 


CHEMICALS 


2    3    4    5    6 


PETROLEUM 


2    3    4    5    6 


RUBBER 


itzilft  Jnt 


2     3    4    5    6 


2    3    4    5    6 


BUILDING 

PRODUCTS 


2     3    4    5    6 


IRON  a  STEEL 


2    3    4    5    6 


NONFERROUS 
METALS 


I     2    3    4    5    6 


MACHINERY 


Ht  jlltt  3111:  adz  ]Ut 

3456         123456         123456         123456         123456 


I  2  3  4  5  6 


TRANSPORTATION         MISCELLANEOUS 
I       EQUIPMENT  MANUFACTURING 


TOTAL 
MANUFACTURING 


MISCELLANEOUS 
MERCHANDISING 


I     2    3    4     5    6 


CHAIN   STORES 


ii  3  jdA  mt 

123456         123456         123456         1234 


2  3  4  5  6 


2  3  4  5  6 


DEPARTMENT 
STORES  X 


I     2     3    4    5    6 


TOTAL 

TRADE  % 
3 


itdi  Jit  jdtt 


2    3    4     5    6 


2    3    4    5    6 


2    3    4     5    6 


Source:  Department  of  Commerce  Survey  of  Business  Taxation. 


variation  was  from  0.91  to  1.94  percent.  In  other  words,  the  pay-roll 
tax  falls  heavier  on  those  firms  where  pay  rolls  are  a  very  major  cost 
item,  while  it  is  lighter  on  firms  that  are  highly  mechanized  (where 
pay  rolls  are  low  with  respect  to  capital  costs).  When  these  figures 
are  further  broken  down  by  size  classes,  the  variations  of  the  pay-roll 
tax  with  the  degree  of  labor  intensity  tend  to  be  greater  in  the  smaller 
size  groups  than  in  the  larger  size  groups. 


Ill 

Ilk      <  III 

( 

■H  i           lill 

T     a    ^    fr    £     >                                                                  £     S     1 

ilUIII 

L(         il 

MK^ucat'  u:  >» 

T    a   e   *>    • 

1 

iillllL 

B    »   \    a    ,:    »    •    s 

Chart  XXXIV 

FEDERAL-STATE  PAY-ROLL  TAX  PAYMENTS  AS  PERCENT  OF  GROSS  MARGIN,  572  LARGE  MANUFACTURING  AND  TRADE  CORPORATIONS  BY  PROFIT  RATE  CLASSES,  1937 


7  =  25-30 

8  =  30  -  35 
9 . 35-40 

10  =  OVER  40 


PER  CENT  FOOD 


JilliilliL     n.l^ 


3    4     5 
PRINTING 


■■■■■■       ■       ■ 

I     23456789    10 


ll=  =l=z  llitz 


3456789    10 

LEATHER 


BUILDING  PRODUCTS       % 


llllll       JUIOiLl      ■       ■ 


23456789    10  123456789    10 

IRON  6  STEEL  NONFERROUS    METALS 


3     4    5    6     7    8    9 

MACHINERY 


III   I—     1 


23456789    10  123456789    10 


JIUIIU 

I     2     3    4     5     6    7    8! 


lUldx   llllll  I  JllUlUk  JmiUllL  jIlltlLC  luiiUUi 


23456789   10 


•/.     CHAIN  STORES 


DEPARTMENT  STORES 


9    10  123456789    10 

TOTAL  TRADE  ». 


liiiiii      iiii —  ilii — I    i~iii~  Jiiimzt 


Source:  Department  of  Commerce  Survey  of  Business  TaiBtion. 


282898— 41— No.  »     (Face  p.  101) 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


101 


The  pay-roll  tax  has  nominally  no  relationship  to  the  profitability 
of  corporations.  Its  liability  results  wherever  persons  are  employed 
in  a  nonexempt  industry  and  varies  with  the  magnitude  of  the  pay 
roll.  Profitable  and  unprofitable  corporations  must  alike  pay  this 
tax,  since  it  is  based  on  a  cost  factor  and  not  on  the  margin  of  profits. 
Yet  it  by  no  means  follows  that  the  pay-roll  tax  impinges  equally  upon 
corporations  of  varying  profitability  and  it  may  f ah  more  heavily  on  the 
less  profitable  group.  In  order  to  examine  this  aspect  of  the  ratio  of 
the  pay-roll  tax  to  gross  margins  the  corporations  were  classified  into 
the  various  profit  groups  as  shown  in  chart  XXXIV  for  21  industries. 
It  is  apparent  from  this  diagram  that  the  pay-roll  tax  ratio  is  larger 
in  the  case  of  the  less  profitable  corporations  than  in  the  case  of  the 
more  profitable  group.  This  observation  applies  to  most  manufac- 
turing industries  and,  somewhat  less  clearly,  to  the  trade  groups.  It 
does  not  apply  to  tobacco,  beverages  (little  or  no  variation)  and 
printing.  To  this  extent  the  pay-roll  may  be  said  to  be  a  "regressive" 
tax,  falling  more  heavily  upon  the  less  profitable  corporations. 

These  data  on  manufacturing  and  trade  corporations  unfortunately 
do  not  show  the  full  range  of  the  variation  in  the  magnitude  of  the 
pay-roll  taxes  since  other  industries  are  perforce  lacking  from  the 
comparison.  It  can  readily  be  assumed  that  the  pay-roll  tax  is  proba- 
bly ver}^  low  in  public  utilities  (other  than  transport)  where  labor  costs 
are  relatively  low  while  capital  costs  are  high.  In  construction,  on 
the  other  hand,  the  pay-roll  taxes  are  probably  high  since  the  labor- 
capital  equation  is  probably  tilted  upward  for  the  former.  But 
enough  data  are  available  to  prove  that  the  pay-roll  tax  adds  to  the 
costs  of  production  in  substantially  different  magnitudes  in  the  various 
industries,  according  to  the  dominance  of  labor  or  mechanization. 
The  present  level  of  the  differential  is  after  all  relatively  slight,  but 
with  the  gradual  step-by-step  increase  of  pay-roll  tax  rates  in  future 
years  the  differential  may  become  of  great  significance  to  the  rela- 
tionship between  labor  and  mechanization. 

This  conclusion  must,  of  course,  be  understood  in  terms  of  the  special 
purposes  for  which  payroll  taxes  are  levied — old  age  and  employment 
security  of  industrial  workers.  The  differential  arises  out  of  the  selec- 
tion of  pay  rolls  as  the  tax  base,  but  labor,  as  is  well  known,  is  only 
one  among  several  cost  factors.  The  security  problems  that  are  to 
be  solved,  or  at  least  ameliorated,  by  the  use  to  which  the  pay-roll 
taxes  are  put  are  by  no  means  peculiar  to  industries  employing  labor 
in  preference  to  machines.  As  a  matter  of  fact  there  have  been  those 
who  have  attributed  a  goodly  share  of  the  rising  economic  problems 
subsumed  under  the  general  term  of  security  to  the  accelerated  growth 
of  mechanization. 

FEDERAL    EXCISE    TAXES  * 

The  various  excise  taxes  imposed  by  the  Federal  Government — 
import  duties,  selective  manufacturers'  and  dealers'  excises,  tobacco, 
and  alcohol  taxes,  stamp  taxes,  the  short-lived  processing  taxes,  etc. — ■ 
are  generally  regarded  by  the  taxed  producer  as  business  costs  which 
he  expects  to  shift,  usually  forward  to  the  consumer,  for  whom. they 

*  This  and  the  following  section  have  been  primarily  contributed  by  Miss  Helen  Tarasov  of  the  Division 
of  Industrial  Economics,  Department  of  Commerce. 

262698— 41— No.  9 8 


202  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

then  become  "indirect  taxes."  But  as  this  report  is  concerned  with 
business  taxes,  it  is  from  the  standpoint  of  the  first  payer  that  the 
Federal  excises  will  be  analyzed.  This  section  on  Federal  excises 
differs  in  several  major  respects  from  the  treatment  of  other  taxes 
in  this  report.  The  relationship  of  such  taxes  to  business  costs  will 
be  measured  in  terms  of  sales  exclusively.  No  size  analysis  is  pre- 
sented, but  industry  differences  are  stressed. 

The  oldest  Federal  excise  was  the  whisky  tax,  imposed  in  1790. 
Tobacco  taxes  were  first  levied  as  a  war  measure  in  1862.  During 
and  immediately  following  the  Civil  War  the  Federal  Government 
imposed  a  variety  of  specific  ad  valorem  taxes  on  commodities,  most 
of  which  were  shortly  repealed.  The  World  War  again  witnessed  the 
enactment  of  a  series  of  manufacturers'  excises  on  a  strange  conglom- 
eration of  ''nonessentials"  ranging  from  chewing  gum  to  life  insurance 
and  from  medicinal  preparations  to  yachts.  The  coming  of  peace 
and  the  return  to  ''normalcy"  led  to  the  automatic  expiration  or 
repeal  of  many  of  these  taxes.  But  others  lingered  on,  for  reasons 
not  overly  clear.  The  record  of  Federal  excises  during  the  period 
from  1918  to  the  present,  as  reported  in  tax-collection  figures,  is  wildly 
erratic,  and  this  may  be  an  understatement. 

Electric  fans  and  lighting  fixtures  were  taxed  from  1920  through 

1924,  but  electrical  energy  remained  tax  free  until  1933.  Firearms 
were  free  in  1918  and  1919,  and  again  between  1927  and  1932,  v/hile 
knives  (including  hunting,  bowie,  dirks,  and  daggers)  were  taxed  only 
in  1920-24,  as  well  as  the  hunting  garments  presumably  worn  with 
them.     Sculptures,   etc.,  were  a  taxable  luxury  until   1927.     From 

1925,  the  excise  on  manufacturing  opium  for  smoking  was  lifted. 
The  adulteration  of  foods  has  been  sporadically  permitted,  fiscally 
speaking,  by  little  loopholes,  such  as  the  nontaxing  of  adulterated 
butter  in  1929  and  in  1931,  of  its  manufacturers  in  1931-32,  of  its 
wholesale  dealers  in  1922,  1932,  1926-30,  and  of  retail  dealers  for  even 
longer.  Various  lapsed  entertainment  excises  were  never  resuscitated, 
being  succeeded  by  levies  on  checks  and  safety-deposit  boxes. 

In  table  IX  is  presented  the  actual  Federal  excise  tax  experience 
of  5,328  manufacturers  in  1938,  as  reported  by  questionnaire  to 
Dun  &  Bradstreet  in  its  recent  survey  of  business  taxation.  The 
magnitude  of  the  tax  is  measured  in  percent  of  sales  and  in  percent  of 
total  tax  payments.  The  highest  tax-sales  ratios  are  reported  for  the 
liquor,  tobacco,  and  oil  industries.  Federal  excise  taxes  also  plaj^  an 
important  role  in  adding  to  business  costs  in  canning,  drugs,  autos, 
transportation  equipment,  and  electrical  apparatus,  in  the  order 
named.  In  the  case  of  most  other  manufacturing  industries  Federal 
excise  taxes  are  either  relatively  unimportant  or  nonextant.  It  is, 
of  course,  quite  improper  to  draw  any  conclusions  from  these  figures 
as  to  the  "tax  burden"  on  the  industry,  for  most  Federal  excises  do  not 
ordinarily  rest  on  the  legal  taxpayer  but  are  passed  along  via  a  complex 
and  subtle  process  of  shifting  to  the  ultimate  consumers  of  the  manu- 
factured product.  The  only  comment  that  can  be  accurately  made  in 
this  frame  of  reference  is  the  marked  contrast  in  the  degree  to  which 
Federal  excises  contribute  to  business  costs  in  different  industries. 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  ][Q3 

Table  IX. — Federal  taxes  on  manufacturing  industries,  1938 


Federal  excises  as  per- 
cent of— 

Sales 

Total  taxes 
paid 

Canning .  _-.  -  .-. -.  ..  .  .  .  .. .  . 

3.71 

3.02 

.59 

1.78 

.82 

.43 

49.10 

32.67 

7.91 

31.26 

3.01 

61  3 

Drugs 

Electrical  apparatus 

65.9 
11  2 

Autos .-                     -     .- -  .     .     ._  _  -  . 

35  4 

Transport  equipment 

Total  manufacturing  excluding.          _.  ...  .          ..          .  .. 

14.8 
11  9 

Distilleries  and  wineries .  .     .      ......_. 

98  0 

Breweries 

Petroleum  refining.   .....             .      ..  .          .  .     ..  _ 

79.3 
34  5 

Tobacco  products .        ..  ..     ...  . 

93  9 

All  manufacturing...  .  .        ...     ..     .  . 

43  6 

Source:  Dun's  Review,  July 


p.  14. 


Federal  excise  tax  payments  of  most  manufacturing  and  trade 
corporations,  as  reported  by  362  identical  corporations  to  the  Depart- 
•ment  of  Commerce  in  its  questionnaire  survey  of  business  taxation  for 
the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  appear  to  have  been 
markedly  declining  in  recent  years.  This  fact  is  readily  apparent  from 
an  examination  of  table  X  which  gives  the  ratio  of  Federal  excise  tax 
payments  to  sales  for  tlie  years  1934-37  by  16  manufacturing  industries 
;and  4  trade  groups.  Taking  manufacturing  as  a  whole  the  Federal 
excise  tax  ratio  declined  from  4.24  percent  in  1934  to  3.57  percent  in 
1935  to  3.16  percent  in  1936  to  2.98  percent  in  1937,  or  a  decline  of 
"30  percent.  This  trend  is  found  for  most  industries  (except  transpor- 
tation equipment).  This  table  also  shows  the  marked  industry  differ- 
ences in  Federal  excise  taxes,  as  noted  in  the  preceding  paragraph. 

Table  X. — Federal  excise  and  State  sales  taxes  as  percent  of  sales  of  362  manufac- 
turing and  trade  corporations,  1934-37 


Industry 

Num- 
ber in 
sample 

Year 

Total  sales 

(millions  of 

dollars) 

Federal 

excise 

(percent 

of  sales) 

State 

sales  taxes 

(percent 

of  sales) 

Food 

30 

1934 

1,040 

1.60 

0.07 

1935 

1,175 

.46 

.06 

1936 

1,228 

.01 

.17 

1937 

1,255 

.40 

.16 

leverages ... 

12 

1934 
1935 

20 
25 

30.94 
33.63 

4.25 

3.75 

1936 

33 

31.62 

3.76 

1937 

36 

28.59 

3.35 

Tobacco... 

10 

1934 

353 

44.27 

.29 

1935 

360 

43.61 

.31 

1936 

392 

42.60 

.29 

1937 

429 

42.81 

.31 

Textiles 

22 

1934 

200 

1.76 

.00 

1935 

252 

.69 

.01 

1936 

281 

.00 

.01 

1937 

281 

.00 

.01 

Lumber .. 

1 

1934 
1935 

4 
5 

.30 

.35 

1936 

7 

.40 

10 

1937 
1934 

i 

.36 

Paper 

.16 

.01 

1935 

79 

.03 

.01 

1936 

93 

.00 

.15 

1937 

117 

.00 

.01 

IQ^  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  X. — Federal  excise  and  State  sales  taxes  as  percent  of  sales  of  362  manufacr- 
turing  and  trade  corporations,  1934-37 — Continued 


Industry 


Num- 
ber in 
sample 


Year 


Total  sales 

(millions  of 

dollars) 


Federal  |     State 
excise     sales  taxes 
(percent     (percent 
of  sales)      of  sales) 


Printing 

Chemicals 

Petroleum 

Rubber 

Leather-. 

Building  products 

Iron,  steel 

Nonferrous  metals 

Machinery  and  tools 

Transportation  equipment,.. 
Miscellaneous  manufacturing 

Total  manufacturing 

Chain  stores.-. 

Department  stores 

Wholesale 

Miscellaneous  trade 

Total  trade 

Total 


19 


18 


62 


47 


22 


312 


26 


362 


1934 
193.5 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 


91 
100 
107 
283 
313 
357 
398 
740 
753 
836 
925 
108 
132 
164 
189 
5 


22 
'   23 

26 
28 
2,319 
2,568 
2,953 
3,213 
8,139 
9,456 
11,234 
12,  885 


3.74 
3.25 
3.13 
2.86 
1.64 
1.51 
1.14 
.98 
4.79 
4.98 
4.94 
4.70 
4.96 
4.79 
4.16 
3.52 


6 

8 

6 

142 

.02 

163 

.01 

221 

.02 

266 

.02 

554 

.01 

716 

.01 

1,013 

.01 

1,  269 

.01 

387 

.01 

436 

.01 

341 

.01 

741 

.00 

691 

.22 

920 

.21 

1,  175 

.19 

1,  521 

.17 

705 

1.58 

965 

1.71 

1.261 

1.81 

1,  503 

1.74 

435 

.67 

498 

.68 

572 

.58 

621 

.57 

5,821 

4.24 

6,888 

3.57 

8,282 

3.16 

9,672 

2.98 

1,496 

.05 

1,598 

.01 

1,764 

.00 

1,864 

.00 

727 

.01 

867 

.03 

1,069 

.03 

1,184 

.02 

74 

80 

94 

136 

.16 

.28 

.03 

.01 

.34 

.21 

.13 

.10 

30.45 

26.07 

23.32 

22.42 


Source:  Department  of  Commerce  Survey  of  Business  Taxation. 


OONCENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER  105 

STATE  SALES  AND  GROSS  INCOME  TAXES 

The  trend  toward  taxation  of  the  consumer  is  particularly  evident 
in  the  recent  history  of  State  sales  and  use  taxes.  Confronted  with 
seriously  curtailed  revenues  from  property  and  income  taxes,  leo:is- 
lators  turned  to  sales  taxes  as  a  means  of  financing  expenditures  for 
social  welfare,  particularly  relief  deficiencies  and  pensions.  The  high 
point  in  sales  taxes  was  in  1937,  with  27  States,  plus  the  District  of 
Columbia  and  New  York  City,  levying  it  (against  6  States  in  July 
1932).  Although  the  number  of  States  fell  to  23  States  plus  New 
York  City  in  1939,  the  proportion  of  State  revenue  derived  from 
sales  taxes  has  risen,  as  a  result  of  better  enforcement,  higher  tax 
rates,  and  the  wide  enactment  of  use  taxes.  Another  manifestation 
of  the  trend  toward  State  taxation  of  the  consumer  is  (a)  adoption 
by  5  States  of  new  tobacco  taxes  in  1939,  m.ake  a  total  of  26  States 
with  tobacco  taxes;  (6)  increase  in  or  extension  of  motor-vehicle  levies 
in  22  States;  and  (c)  raising  or  continuance  of  gasoline  tax  rates  in  7 
States. 

There  are  distinct  regional  preferences  apparent  for  certain  taxes, 
and  their  distribution  will,  of  course,  affect  business  costs  to  a  con- 
siderable measure,  with  the  actual  effect  on  sales  dependent  on  in- 
dustrial location  or  proximity  to  nontaxed  areas.  Thus,  none  of  the 
Western  States  except  Washington,  Utah,  and  Arizona  tax  tobacco, 
while  this  tax  is  particularly  popular  in  the  South  and  more  recently 
in  the  East.  The  sales  tax  is  found  in  no  Atlantic  Seaboard  State, 
but  originated  in  and  is  most  represented  by  the  Middle  West,  where 
in  certain  sections  it  has  expanded  into  a  gross-receipts  tax  on  busi- 
ness. A  special  study  by  the  Department  of  Commerce  indicates 
that  regional  differences  in  State  sales  taxes  affected  the  transfer  of 
business  only  under  particularly  favorable  conditions  for  such  transfer, 
i.  e.,  conveniently  located  retail  establishments  across  a  State  border 
within  easy  reach.  Since  the  tax  is  usually  in  fact  as  well  as  by  law 
transferred  to  the  consumer,  the  transfer  of  business  is  obviously 
limited.^ 

Table  XI  gives  the  sales- tax  experience  for  6,000  manufacturing, 
2,000  wholesalers,  and  16,000  retailers  as  reported  to  Dun  &  Brad- 
street  for  1938,  measuring  sales  as  percents  of  {a)  sales  and  (6)  total 
taxes.  The  record  for  any  specific  industry  is  apparent  upon  inspec- 
tion. It  is  quite  evident  that,  although  m.anufacturing  in  general 
pays  a  higher  percentage  of  aggregate  sales  in  the  form  of  State  sales 
taxes,  such  taxes  nevertheless  are  of  less  importance  in  adding  to 
business  costs,  as  other  taxes  are  substantially  larger.  Only  12.3 
percent  of  its  tax  costs  are  due  to  these  taxes,  while  32.7  percent  of 
all  retailers'  taxes  are  caused  by  them.  Thus,  although  the  percentage 
of  aggregate  sales  taken  by  these  taxes  is  only  0.70  percent,  they  are 
more  noticeable  in  view  of  the  lesser  role  of  other  taxes,  since  all  taxes 
on  retailers  are  only  2.14  percent.  Wholesalers,  who  pay  only  half 
the  total  taxes  on  aggregate  sales  that  manufacturers  do,  must  reckon 
with  sales  and  excises  as  a  prime  business  cost,  as  they  are  61  percent 
of  the  total  taxes  paid. 

5  H.  P.  Warhurst,  "The  Effect  of  General  States  Tax  Levies  on  Retail  Sales  Increase,  1933-35"  (Bureau 
of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce). 


IQQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  XI. — State  sales  taxes  as  percent  of  sales,  1936 


PART  I.  MANUFACTURING 


Percent 

Meat  packing 0.  01 

Hosiery .  01 

Nonferrous  metal  products .01 

Transport  and  agricultural  ma- 
chinery   .02 

Textile  weaving .02 

Shoes .  02 

Newspapers       and       periodicals 

(large) .  02 

Hardware .04 

Canning  and  food  manufacturing.  .  04 

Flour  and  feed  milling .06 

Dairies,  cream.eries,  m.ilk  dealers.  .  07 

Drugs,  perfumes,  cosmetics .  07 

Clothing .  07 

Paper  and  paper  products .08 

Clay  and  glass  products .08 

"Other"  manufacturing .08 

Electrical  apparatus  and  appli- 
ances   .08 

Iron  and  steel .  08 

Automobiles .08 


Percent 

Machine  shop  products 0.  09 

Foundries .  11 

Engines  and  machinery ,11 

Newspapers  (small) .  11 

Baking  and  confectionery .12 

"All  other"  forest  products .  16 

Stone  and  stone  products .  19 

Printing     and      bindery      (book 

jobs) .  21 

Industrial  chemicals .  21 

Paints,  varnish,  and  lacquers : .23 

Furniture .  25 

Distilleries  and  wineries .29 

Lumber  and  planing  mills .  35 

Beverages — nonalcoholic .  73 

Ice  manufacturing .  87 

Breweries 6.  48 

Petroleum  refining 11.  47 

Total,   except  distilleries,   petro- 
leum, tobacco .09 

All  manufacturing .85 


PART  II.  WHOLESALE  TRADE 


Dairy  and  poultry  products 

Produce  and  fruit 

Meat  and  fish 

Dry  goods  and  apparel 

"Other"  wholesaling 

Machinery  and  equipm.ent 

Groceries 

Lum.ber,  building  material,  and 

fuel 

Hardware 

Electrical  goods  and  appliances. 
Automotive  equipment 


Percent 
0.00 
.03 
.04 
.  12 
.  12 
.  15 
.  17 

.  19 
.20 
.20 
.22 


Percent 

Paper  and  paper  products 0.  23 

Paints  and  varnishes .  25 

Plumbing  and  heating  supplies..  .  27 

Drugs  and  industrial  chemicals..  .  31 

Other  miscellaneous  supplies .36 

Confectionery  and  tobacco  pro- 
ducts   .90 

Alcoholic  beverages 4.  65 

Petroleum  products 12.  38 

All     wholesale     (except     alcohol 

and  petroleum) .  19 

All  wholesale 2.  16 


PART  III.  RETAIL  TRADE 


Percent 

Drugs   and   cosmetics — chains..  0.  15 

Mail-order  houses .20 

Farm.ers  supply  stores .  26 

Bakeries — independent .31 

Florists  and  nurseries .32 

Shoes — chains .  34 

Bakeries — chains .  40 

Filling  stations .43 

Groceries — independent .  45 

Hardware  and  farm  implements.  .  49 

Meats  and  fish .50 

Other  food  and  beverage  stores.  _  .  54 
Auto  accessories  and  parts — in- 
dependent   .59 

Motor  vehicle  dealers .61 

Variety     stores — chains .  62 

Department    stores — chains .  63 

Fam.ily  clothing .70 

Country  general  stores .72 


Percent 
Radio,  electrical,   gas  household 

appliances 0.  72 

Jewelry .73 

Shoes — independent .74 

Paint,  wallpaper,  glass .  74 

Groceries  and  meats — independ- 
ent   .74 

Lumber  and  building  materials..  .  75 
Auto     accessories     and     parts — 

chains .75 

Women's  clothing,  accessories — 

independent 0.  77 

Coal  and  other  fuel .79 

Variety  stores — independent .  86 

General    merchandise    and    dry 

goods .86 

Department      stores — independ- 
ent   .89 

Furniture .89 


OONOENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER  107 

Table  XI. — State  sales  taxes  as  percent  of  sales,  1936 — Contmued 
PART  III.  RETAIL  TRADE— Continued 

Page  Page 


Farm  implements 0.  93 

Drugs  and  cosmetics — independ- 
ent   .94 

Men's,   boys'   clothing,   and  fur- 
nishings   .  96 

Groceries       and       m.eats — small 

chains .98 

''All  other"  retail  stores 1.  00 

Stationery,  books,  newsdealers.  _  1.  05 

Source:  Dun's  Review,  July  1938,  pp.  14-15. 


House  furnishings  and  floor  cov- 
erings   1.  11 

Restaurant,  etc. — independent- _  1.  14 

Restaurant,     etc. — chains 1.  55 

Hardware .70 

All  retailing .70 

Independent  retailers .70' 

Chain  organizations .74 


The  role  of  State  sales  taxes  throughout  retailing  is  far  more  sig- 
nificant than  for  wholesaling,  where  they  account  for  only  13  percent 
of  total  taxes  (if  alcoholic  beverages  and  petroleum  products  are  ex- 
cluded), while  they  form  about  one-third  of  total  retailers'  taxes,  and 
fall  below  25  percent  for  just  over  one-fourth  of  the  types  of  retailing- 
involved. 

The  effect  on  industrial  activity  depends  on  whether  the  variable- 
cost  tax  is  passed  on  to  the  consumer  and  in  what  form  (lower  quality^ 
lesser  quantity,  higher  price)  or  absorbed  by  the  manufacturer  or 
trader,  or  passed  back  as  lower  prices  for  labor  or  raw  materials,  a& 
may  be  the  case  if  a  product  is  subject  to  elastic  demand  and  if  its 
producer  has  a  strong  position  vis-a-vis  his  employees  or  his  supplier. 
A  shift  in  sales  volume  may  affect  business  costs  adversely;  particu- 
larly if  fixed  costs  are  large,  the  decrease  in  variable  taxes  resulting- 
from  a  decline  in  sales  may  never  compensate  for  the  lower  turn-over. 
Contrariwise,  the  higher  variable  taxes  on  increasing  sales  may  not 
be  a  deterrent,  since  the  margin  increases  with  volume.  Nor  will 
industry  with  high  variable  costs  be  discouraged  from  expanding  by 
commodity  or  sales  taxes,  but  it  will  have  to  regard  them  as  a  basic 
cost  factor  when  it  sets  prices.  For  the  fixed-cost  industry,  the 
variable  taxes  are  a  secondary  factor  in  price  policy,  since  it  must 
first  of  all  seek  volume,  and  if  demand  is  elastic,  it  may  be  preferable 
to  absorb  at  least  some  of  the  commodity  and  sales  taxes  for  the  sake 
of  expanding  the  market. 

How  each  industry  treats  these  variable  taxes  depends  on  its  own 
peculiar  cost  and  competitive  conditions.  Nor  is  it  known  what  th& 
consumption  of  a  product  or  group  of  products  might  have  been  in 
the  absence  of  a  levy  on  it — although  figures  do  show  that  the  con- 
sumption of  the  most  heavily  taxed  commodities,  viz,  gasoline^ 
liquor,  cigarettes,  has  risen  steadily  despite  the  onerous  tax  levies 
imposed  on  them  and  almost  certainly  passed  on  to  the  consumer. 
Concretely,  it  appears  that  the  sharp  and  sudden  increase  of  the 
tobacco  tax  in  Wisconsin  last  year  led  to  only  a  temporary  decrease 
in  State  cigarette  sales,  and  that  tax  receipts  are  now  fulfilling- 
expectations. 

Other  factors,  apparently,  play  a  prime  role  in  determining  sales 
volumiC  of  semiluxury  products  at  least,  with  tax  rates  only  reinforc- 
ing or  temporarily  counteracting  a  trend  established  by  general  in- 
come level,  custom,  fashion,  weather,  etc.  Fluctuations  of  business 
costs  therefore  depend  only  indirectly  on  variable  taxes,  and  the 
relationship  is  further  complicated  by  the  effect  of  whatever  policy 
is  followed  on  sales  volume  and  its  reaction  on  business  costs.  The- 
effect  on  consumption  must  be  regarded  as  the  prime  consideration. 


CHAPTER  X 

FIXED-COST  TAXES:  STATE  PROPERTY  TAXES  AND  SPECIAL 
TAXES  ON  CORPORATIONS 

The  ''fixed-costs"  taxes  appear  to  be  ''fixed"  in  more  senses  than 
one.  They  are  termed  as  "fixed-costs"  since  their  magnitude  is 
usually  unrelated  to  the  volume  of  industrial  activity  but  is  instead 
based  upon  the  value  of  property — real,  personal,  or  intangibles  (as 
a  "franchise").  In  this  respect  they  are  assimilable  to  interest  and 
rent  costs.  But  these  taxes  may  be  regarded  as  "fixed"  in  another 
sense — their  magnitude  has  changed  very  slightly  over  the  recent 
years.  Thus  the  dollar  amount  of  "fixed-cost"  taxes  of  an  identical 
group  of  362  large  manufacturing  and  trade  corporations  increased 
only  17  percent  between  1934  and  1937,  while  sales  increased  58 
percent  and  net  profits  increased  112  percent.  The  ratio  of  such 
taxes  to  sales  actually  declined  from  1.19  percent  in  1934  to  1.04 
percent  in  1935  to  0.90  percent  in  1936  and  to  0.83  percent  in  1937. 
This  decline  appeared  in  all  size  classes.^  Of  course  there  have  been 
some  variations  in  the  magnitude  of  such  tax  payments — depending 
upon  the  rate  structure,  the  methods  of  assessment,  and  property 
values,  but  these  changes  have  been  relatively  minor  in  comparison 
to  changes  in  the  volume  of  income,  sales,  and  pay-roll  tax  payments. 

PROPERTY  TAXES 

The  oldest  and  still  very  important  tax  collected  from  business 
enterprise  is  the  State  and  local  taxes  on  real  and  personal  property. 
It  is  a  tax  which  is  periodically  and  universally  condemned.  Its 
relative  position  in  the  tax  hierarchy  has  been  steadily  declining  for 
several  decades.  It  was  never  employed  by  the  Federal  Government, 
in  part  for  constitutional  reasons.  It  has  been  gradually  abandoned 
or  sharply  curtailed  for  purposes  of  State  revenue.^  Yet  the  property 
tax  is  still  the  main  tax  source  of  most  local  governments  (as  shown  in 
chart  I,  supra),  whether  they  be  counties,  cities,  school  districts,  park 
districts,  sanitary  districts,  health  districts,  mosquito-abatement 
districts,  or  some  other  of  the  fabulously  numerous  types  of  special- 
purpose,  ad  hoc  authorities. 

The  magnitude  of  the  property  tax  payments  of  a  bsuiness  enter- 
prise is  a  function  of  three  factors — (a)  the  legal  rate  of  the  tax  and 
the  relationship  between  (6)  the  assessed  value,  and  (c)  the  actual 
value  of  the  property  taxed.  The  property  tax  rates  vary  from  State 
to  State,  from  county  to  county,  from  city  to  cit^^,  and  from  town- 
ship to  township,  and  so  through  that  labyrinthine  maze  of  175,000 

1  See  Appendix  D. 

2  Nevada  is  the  single  State  obtaining  a  major  share  of  its  revenue  from  property  taxes,  presumably  m 
substantia]  part  from  mining  properties.  See  U,  S.  Bureau  of  the  Census,  Financial  Statistics  of  States,. 
1937,  table  1. 

109 


IIQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

units  of  government  in  the  United  States.  The  tremendous  varia- 
tion of  the  property  tax  rates  occurs  not  only  between  different  units 
of  government  but  may  also  be  found  within  the  same  area  (e.  g., 
in  the  Chicago  metropolitan  area).  These  variations  are  so  complex 
and  so  sliifting  that  no  general  statement  can  at  present  be  made 
with  an}^  degree  of  precision.^ 

Empirical  studies  of  the  administration  of  the  property  tax  have 
generally  shown  that  the  assessment  of  property  tends  to  be  regres- 
sive—that is,  ''a  definite  and  pronounced  tendenc^^  for  the  average 
assessment  ratio  to  decline  as  the  value  of  the  property  *  *  * 
increased."  "^  The  actual  tax  experience  of  5,000  manufacturers, 
1,900  wholesalers,  and  16,000  retailers  filing  special  tax  data  with 
Dun  &  Bradstreet  for  1938  confirm  this  generalization.  The  rela- 
tive magnitude  of  the  property  tax  (measured  in  percent  of  sales) 
tends  to  vary  inversely  with  business  size  (bp^sed  on  4  sales  classes) — 
that  is,  the  tax  ratios  are  larger  on  the  smaller  enterprises  and  smaller 
on  the  larger  enterprises.     See  chart  XXXV. 

The  property  tax  is  ''regressive"  in  another  sense — it  is  relatively 
larger  on  the  less  profitable  corporations  and  smaller  on  the  more 
profitable  group.  This  fact  is  clearly  apparent  from  an  analysis  of 
the  tax  experience  of  572  manufacturing  corporations  for  1937  which 
have  been  grouped  into  10  profit  classes,  based  on  the  ratio  of  profits 
to  invested  capital.  In  substantially  each  case  the  property  tax  is 
relatively  higher  on  the  unprofitable  and  low  profitable  group  and 
relatively  lower  on  the  highly  profitable  group.     See  chart  XXXVI. 

BUSINESS    PRIVILEGE    AND    LICENSE    TAXES 

Another  type  of  the  fixed-cost  taxes  is  the  group  of  special  business 
taxes  which  are  imposed  at  either  a  flat  rate  or  are  based  on  some 
capital  magnitude.  Nominally  the  Federal  Government  imposes  a  cap- 
ital stock  tax  at  the  rate  of  $1  per  $1,000  declared  capitalization,  but 
as  has  already  been  shown  in  chapter  V  of  this  report,  the  Federal  cap- 
ital stock  tax  is  probably  more  like  an  income  tax  than  any  other  type 
of  tax.  It  is  of  coulee  like  the  fixed-cost  taxes  in  that  it  must  be  paid 
regardless  of  the  volume  of  business  activity  or  the  magnitude  of 
corporation  profits,  provided  a  positive  capital  declaration  had  been 
filed  with  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Kevenue.  If  no  profits  had  been 
anticipated  the  corporation  could  have  declared  a  capitalization  of 
zero  or  the  equivalent,  and  no  capital  stock  tax  need  have  been  paid. 
The  Federal  capital  stock  tax  is  essentially  like  an  income  tax  in  that 
its  magnitude  is  more  or  less  based  on  capitalized  earning  power,  at 
least  as  anticipated. 

State  and  local  taxes  on  corporations  may  be  classified  mto  three 
principal  types,  (a)  corporation  organization  and  entrance  taxes, 
(6)  annual  corporate  taxes  based  on  capital  stock  or  some  variant 
thereof,  and  (c)  annual  corporate  taxes  based  on  or  measured  by  net 
income. 

The  initial  tax  costs  of  organizing  a  corporation  are  usually  so  small 
in  actual  dollar  outlays  that  they  cannot  be  accurately  said,  to  consti- 
tute any  substantial  deterrent  to  the  establishment  of  new  enterprises 

3  Special  constitutional  limitations  may  of  course  put  upper  limits  to  the  range  of  the  variations. 

4  Joseph  D.  Silvcrherz,  The  Assessment  of  Real  Property  in  the  United  States  (Special  Report  of  the 
l^ew  York  State  Tax  Commission,  No.  10),  p.  213. 


(J) 


q:  CO 
Q-< 

<^ 

w     I-  O 

^     CC     . 

UJ  CO 

Q_     UJ 

O  fr 

£§ 

<  ~ 

o 

o 


<'5  8  8°.g- 
J8  S~i8 


ii 


& 


Chart  XXXV — Continued 

STATE  AND  LOCAL   PROPERTY  TAXES  AS  PER  CENT  OF  SALES 
INDUSTRIES,  CLASSIFIED  BY  SALES 

1938 
PART  E-  1,912  WHOLESALE  CONCERNS 


SALES    CLASSES 


PER  C£NT  FOOD 


- 

III! 

ALCOHOLIC 
^NT       BEVERAGES 

- 

MM^M. 

PER  CENT     WHOLESALE 


I 


Ui 


PER  CENT       PETROLEUM 


mllA 


source:   To.  Su..«,  -orl.  sKaeli  of  Iht  B 

Department  of  Commerce. 


d  Stotiflict  Divitionof  Own  and  Bra 


262098— 41— No.  9     (Face  p.  110)     No.  2. 


XIjlil.^ 


■<,t    tvv-:     ti^- 


.:ij  i'jk..i.\. 


CO  00 

_J 

o 

CO 


[J      9 


9         u,  I 

«         g  I 

I  »         i  ■ 


I  "    <5 


5? 
x< 

I-O 

ql 


< 
o 

Q. 
CC 
O 
O 

ujiS 

|S8 
^3 
g" 

§i= 

UJ 

< 

_J 

CM 
If) 


I  9        p 

- 

■    -     Su 


,  I 


:  I 


iL 
1^ 


1 

-f 

B 

OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  m 

in  the  corporate  form.^  Yet  the  small  pecuniary  or  fiscal  importance 
of  such  taxes  should  not  permit  a  disregard  of  the  marked  size  dis- 
criminations characteristic  of  the  relevant  statutory  provisions  of 
most  States.  The  corporate  organization  entrance  tax  is  t3^pically 
based  on  some  element  of  the  financial  structure  of  the  corporation 
(e.  g.,  paid-in  capital  stock).  In  more  than  half  the  States^  the  tax 
is  regressive  on  the  face  of  the  statute;  that  is,  the  tax  rate  is  relatively 
lower  on  corporations  with  large  capital.  In  one  State  (Georgia)  the 
tax  is  a  flat  amount  ($15)  while  in  another  State  (Arizona)  the  magni- 
tude of  the  tax  depends  upon  the  number  of  folios  filed.  In  19  States  ^ 
the  tax  is  nominally  proportional;  that  is,  the  rate  of  the  tax  is  the 
same  irrespective  of  the  amount  of  capital  involved  in  the  base.  Only 
in  South  Carolina  is  the  tax  rate  progressive  in  form;  that  is,  the  statu- 
tory rate  is  relatively  higher  on  corporations  with  large  capital.^ 

A  maximum  tax  (ranging  from  $100  in  Alabama  to  $2,500  in  Louis- 
iana, Texas,  and  Wasliington)  is  set  in  at  least  7  of  the  25  States  where 
the  tax  is  regressive,  while  substantially  all  the  States  set  a  minimum 
tax.  The  one  feature  operates  in  favor  of  large  corporations  while  the 
latter  provision  is  somewhat  to  the  disadvantage  of  small  corpora- 
tions. The  problem  of  effective  administration  is  usually  weightier 
than  the  potential  yield  of  revenue,  with  the  result  that  the  actual 
amounts  collected  are  usually  insubstantial  in  dollar  magnitude.^ 
In  a  special  study  of  corporate  organization  and  entrance  taxes,  the 
National  Industrial  Conference  Board  concluded  that  such  taxes 
are — 

heaviest  on  corporations  witii  a  small  capitalization  and  light  on  corporations 
with  large  capital  -'=  *  *  hearing  down  upon  the  small  corporation,  which 
cannot  easily  avoid  the  tax,  and  treating  gently  the  large  corporation,  which 
might  otherwise  be  induced  to  arrange  its  method  of  incorporation  so  as  to  avoid 
a  considerable  part  of  tlio  tax.'o 

The  State  corporate  privilege  taxes  (annual)  are  usually  based  on 
capital  stock,  variously  defined  as  ''authorized,"  ''issued,"  "out- 
standing," "subscribed,"  "paid-up,"  or  a  combination  of  the  fore- 
going. In  a  few  States  surplus  and/or  undivided  profits  are  also 
included  in  the  tax  base.  Indebtedness  is  specifically  included  only 
in  tw^o  States. ^^  In  no  State  is  the  corporation  tax  progressive  in  its 
statutory  terms.  Regressivity  appears  on  the  statutory  face  of  the 
franchise  tax  in  at  least  21  States,  in  12  of  wdiich  a  maximum  tax 
limit  is  specified. ^^     To  this  group  of  21  States  should  be  added  the 

5  Accurate  figures  on  tax  collections  from  this  source  are  unfortunately  lacking.  The  Treasury  estimated 
that  in  1938  the  States  collected  only  $313,000,000  in  the  form  of  corporate  privilege  taxes.  Of  this  figure 
approximately  $200,000,000  were  corporate  income  taxes.  The  greater  share  of  the  remaining  $100,000,000 
was  presumably  derived  from  annual  franchise  taxes  other  than  on  income.  , 

6  Arkansas,  California,  Colorado,  Delaware,  Florida,  Idaho,  Kansas,  Maine,  Indiana,  Mississippi.  Mon- 
tana, Nebraska,  Nevada,  New  Hampshire,  North  Dakota,  Ohio,  Oregon,  Rhode  Island,  South  Dakota, 
Tennessee,  Texa.s,  Vermont,  Virginia,  Washington,  and  Wj^oming.  ,,.  ,  .         ,^- 

^  Alabama,  Connecticut,  Illinois,  Indiana.  Iowa,  Kentucky.  Louisiana.  Massachusetts,  Michigan,  Minne- 
sota, Missouri,  New  Jersey,  New  Mexico,  New  York,  North  Carolina,  Oklahoma,  Pennsylvania,  Utah,  and 
Wisconsin.  ,        ,       m      n     i 

8  Apparently  no  tax  is  imposed  bv  the  State  of  West  Virginia.  All  statements  are  based  on  Tax  Systems 
of  the  W^orld  (7th  ed.,  1938).  pp.  17r,-80.  . ,     ,  ^-      ^v,  ^  4^u 

e  "The  organization  charges  are  so  small  an  item  in  the  budget  of  an  individual  corporation  that  they  are 
of  negligible  importance."  National  Industrial  Conference  Board,  State  and  Local  Taxation  of  Business 
Corporations  (1931),  p.  42. 

11  E.  g'.',  in  Louisiana  and  Texas.  See  a  special  research  bulletin  issued  by  the  Federation  of  Tax  Ad- 
ministrators on  Annual  Corporation  Franchise  Taxes  CJanuary  21,  1939).  ,,,.,.        *    TVT  X,      1    * 

12  Delaware,  Florida*,  Georgia*,  Idaho*,  Illinois*,  Kansas*,  Maine,  Maryland,  Michigan*,  Nebraska  , 
New  Hampshire*,  New  Jersey,  Oklahoma*,  Oregon*,  Tennessee*,  Texas,  Vermont*.  Washington*.  West 
Virginia,  and  Wyoming.  The  asterisk  identifies  the  States  imposing  a  maximum  tax.  In  Maryland, 
Oregon,  and  West  Virginia  foreign  corporations  are  taxed  at  somewhat  higher  rates  than  domestic  cor- 
Dorations. 


112 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


three  States  imposing  a  flat  rate  franchise  tax  ^^  and  perhaps  the  two 
States  purporting  to  collect  a  franchise  tax  at  general  propert}^  rates/^ 
making  a  total  of  26  States  having  ''regressive"  corporation  taxes. - 
The  franchise  tax  is  nominally  proportional  in   14   States, ^^  but  a 
minimum  tax  is  usually  required,  irrespective  of  the  size  of  capital  in: 
the  tax  base. 

The  ''actual  signiflcance"  of  these  size  differences  in  State  cor- 
porate privilege  taxes  were  found  by  the  National  Industrial  Con- 
ference Board  to  be  "relatively  slight,"  except  possibly  in  the  case  of 
"the  small  corporation  doing  chiefly  a  local  business  that  has  grounds 
for  complaint  because  of  the  exemption  of  its  unincorporated  com- 
petitors." ^^ 

The  State  corporate  privilege  taxes  are  also  "regressive"  in  the 
sense  that  they  are  relatively  heavier  on  the  less  profitable  corpora- 
tions and  lighter  on  the  more  profitable  corporations.  This  statement 
is  graphically  shown  in  table  XII  wherein  are  plotted  the  actual  tax 
experience  of  572  manufacturing  and  trade  corporations,  classified  by 
10  profit  classes  (based  on  the  ratio  of  "net  before  interest"  to  in- 
vested capital,  including  long-term  debt). 

Table  XII. — State  corporate  taxes  as  percent  of  gross  margin,  by  profit  rate  classes  ^ 

and  industries,  1937 

Part  I.  FRANCHISE  TAX  AS  PERCENT  OF  GROSS  MARGIN 


Profit  rate  classes- 

Industries 

Defi- 
cit 

Under 
5 

5  to 
10 

10  to 
15 

15  to 
20 

20  to 
25 

25  to 
30^ 

30  to 
35 

35  to 
40 

Over 
40 

Food 

0.0 

0.1 

0.1 
.3 
.0 
.1 

0.1 
.3 
.0 
.2 
.1 
.2 
2.2 
1.1 

0.3 

'"."3" 
.2 

0.2 
.  1 
.1 
.0 

0.0 

0.0 

0.1 

0  0 

Tobacco 

.1 

Bevera?es_  _  ...      ..        .._  . 

.2 
.2 

'"."i" 

"'.2' 

.0 

.  1 

Textiles 

Lumber,.-  ...     . ._  .  .  . 

Paper 

.4 

.1 

.2 

.2 

.0 

.3 

.3 

.1 

.1 

.2 

.1 

.1 

.  1 

.2 

.1 

.16 

.5 

.2 

.1 

.4 

'".2" 

.2 
.0 
.0 

Printing.     ... . 

.0 
.3 

.0 
.2 

Chemicals 

.1 

.0 

Petroleum  .... 

Rubber 

.2 

.8 
.2 

'".'2' 
.1 
1.2 
.1 
.1 
.4 
.5 
.28 
.0 
.1 
.5 
.1 
.09 

"'."6" 
.1 
.2 
.0 
.0 
.1 
.1 
.18 
.2 
.0 
.3 

.1 

Leather.  ..     ...  . 

Building  products .  .. 

.1 

.0 

.1 

.2 

.1 

.  1 

.16 

.2 

.1 

.1 
.5 
.2 
.  1 
.0 
2 

!03 
.2 

.1 

.1 

"'.'2" 

.  1 

Iron  and  steel 

Nonferrous  metals . . 

-.1 

:\ 

.26 
.1 

.3 

Machinery 

.2 
.3 
.5 
.23 

.4 

.1 

.1 

.0 

.08 

.0 
.1 

.0 

Transportation  equipment 

Miscellaneous  manufacturing 

.0 

Total  manufacturing .  . 

.07 

.05 

Chain  stores 

Department  stores.. . 

Wholesale 

.1 

Miscellaneous  merchandise 

.0 
.13 

.1 

.20 

Total  merchandise 

.30 

.40 

.14 

.12 

•3  Arizona,  Connecticut,  and  Nevada. 

"  Minnesota  and  Indiana  (said  not  to  be  enforced  in  the  latter  State). 

•5  Alabama,  Arkansas*,  Colorado*,  Kentucky*,  Louisiana*,  Mississippi*,  Missouri,  New  Mexico*,  North 
Carolina*,  Ohio*,  Pennsylvania,  Rhode  Island,  South  Carolina*,  and  Wisconsin*.  The  asterisk  indicates 
that  a  minimum  tax  is  required. 

16  State  and  Local  Taxniion  of  Business  Corporations  (1931),  p.  127.  This  report  added  that  the  "ad- 
vantages of  large-scale  operation  more  tlian  offset  the  special  burden  of  corporate  taxation."  On  an  earlier 
page  (12.5)  it  reported  that  "on  the  wliole,  the  taxes  levied  on  corporations  in  the  leading  industrial  States 
appear  to  be  heavier  than  those  levied  in  the  primarily  agricultural  States,  a  fact  which  suggests  that  such 
factors  as  access  to  raw  materials  and  markets,  the  character  of  transportation  facilities,  and  the  extent  of 
the  supply  of  labor  are  usuallv  more  important  considerations  in  promoting  industrial  growth  than  the- 
matter  of  relative  tax  burdens." 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  PO\\ER 


113 


1  ABLE  XII. — State  corporate  taxes  as  percent  of  gross  margin,  by  profit  rate  classes 
and  industries,  1937 — Continued 


Part  II.  STATE  INCOME 

TAXES  AS 

PERCENT  OF  GROSS  MARGIN 

Profit  rate  classes 

Industries 

Defi- 
cit 

Under 

6 

5  to 
10 

10  to 
15 

15  to 
20 

20  to 
25 

25  to 
30 

30  to 
35 

35  to 
40 

Over 
40 

Food 

0.2 

0.1 

0.3 
.3 

0.4 

1.2 

0.6 
.2 
.5 

0.1 

1.5 

\  \ 

•Tobacco 

0.4 

Beverages 

.0 
.3 

.1 

1.0 

'Textiles 

.1 

.2 

.5 
.1 

"".'5' 
.3 

0.9 

Lumber.        -  .. 

Paper    ..--.-....     -..     . 

.1 
.0 
.1 

.4 
.2 
2 
'.2 
.1 
.2 
.3 
.1 
.9 
.3 
.1 
.3 
.1 
.3 
.2 
.0 

.3 

Printing.    

.6 
.6 

.5 
.1 

Chemicals - 

.0 

.5 

Petroleum     --.-._ 

.3 

Rubber 

.0 

.1 

.  1 
.2 
.1 
.1 
.2 
.0 
,1 
.3 
.0 
.1 

.2 
.1 
.3 
.2 
.1 
.3 
.3 
.2 
1.4 

.2 

Leather ._ 

Building  products                                   j 

.2 
.1 
.8 
.5 
.2 
.6 
.4 
.2 

.4 
.8 
.2 
.3 
.1 
.2 
.4 

.0 
.6 
.2 
.4 
.1 
.6 
.5 

.7 

1.3 

Iron  and  steel _-     ._ 

Nonferrous  metals ._     -           . 

Machinery ■, 

Transportation  eq  uipment ! 

Miscellaneous  manufacturing 

.'0 
.10  : 

.2 
.0 

.2 
.1 

.6 

.2 
.1 

Chain  stores       __                       - 

.1 

Department  stores. .  _ 

Wholesale -_ 

.5 

Miscellaneous  merchandise 

.3 

.  1 

.  4 

1 

Note.— The  profit  rate  is  based  on  the  percentile  ratio  of  net  before  interest  to  invested  capital  (includ- 
:  ing  long-term  debt). 

Source:  Department  of  Commerce  Sirrvey  of  Business  Taxation. 

Somewhat  offsetting  this  picture  of  regressivety  in  the  State  taxa- 
tion of  corporations  is  the  fact  that  (a)  in  at  least  8  States  the  fran- 
chise tax  on  corporate  capital  has  been  practically  superseded  by  a 
tax  on  corporate  income  ^^  and  (6)  in  some  24  States  ^^  corporations 
are  subject  to  an  income  tax  as  well  as  the  annual  franchise  and 
privilege  taxes. 

The  National  Industrial  Conference  Board  has  commented  on  the 
shift  from  a  capital-stock  tax  to  an  income  tax  as  tending  ''to  accen- 
tuate the  tax  burden  on  business  corporations." 

Capital-stock  tax  bears  on  the  prosperous  and  unsuccessful  corporations  alike. 
The  income  tax  relieves  the  latter  and  places  a  heavier  burden  on  the  former, 
unless  a  capital-stock  tax  is  used  as  a  minimum  for  the  income  tax  *  *  *_ 
[The  income  tax]  bears  more  heavily  than  a  capital-stock  tax  on  large  corpora- 
tions, while  for  small  corporations  the  reverse  is  true.^^ 

State  taxes  on  corporate  income  have  been  steadily  growing  in 
importance  in  recent  years,  w^hether  measured  in  terms  of  the  number 
of  States  imposing  such  taxes  or  in  terms  of  the  dollar  magnitude  of 
taxes  collected  from  specific  corporations.  Between  1930  and  1940 
more  than  17  States  20  adopted  taxes  applicable  to  corporate  income. 

17  California,  Iowa.  Massachusetts.  Montana,  New  York,  North  Dakota,  South  Dakota,  and  Utah. 
In  Massachusetts  there  is  siill  said  to  be  a  "corporate  excess"  tax  but  it  is  substantially  merged  with  the 
income  tax.  Under  the  so-called  franchise  tax  of  New  York,  which  is  fundamentally  based  on  net  income, 
a  minimum  fax  of  $25  is  requi-ed— in  ofTect  a  privilege  tax  on  capital  for  unprofitable  corporatir ns.  The 
North  Dakota  and  South  Dakota  taxes  contain— progressive  rate  structures. 

18  Alabama,  Arizona,*  Arkansas,  Colorado,  Connecticut.  Georgia,  Idaho,*  Kansas.  Kentucky,  Louis- 
iana, Maryland,  Minnesota,  Mississippi,*  Missouri,  New  Mexico,  North  Carolina,  Oregon,  Oklahoma, 
Pennsylvania,  South  Carolina,  Tennessee,  Vermont,  Virginia,  and  W'sconsin.*  The  asterisk  indicates 
that  the  rate  'Structure  is  progressively  graduated. 

19  State  and  Local  Taxation  of  Business  Corporations  (1931),  p.  87. 

20 1931— Idaho,  Ohio,  Oklahoma,  Utah,  and  Vermont;  1933.— Alabama,  Arizona,  Kansas,  Minnesota,  and 
New  Mexico;  1934— Iowa  and  Louisiana;  1935— Pennsylvania  and  South  Dakota;  1936— Kentucky;  1937— 
Colorado  and  Maryland. 


J^]^4  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Taking  an  identical  group  of  362  large  corporations  for  a  recent 
4-year  period  (1934-37),  State  taxes  on  corporate  incomes  increased 
217  percent,  a  rate  of  growth  greater  than  that  for  any  other  type  of 
tax,  while  State  franchise  and  privilege  taxes  increased  only  125  per- 
cent, or  only  half  as  rapidly  as  the  former.  Measured  in  terms  of 
sales,  State  taxes  on  corporate  income  steadily  increased  from  0.08 
percent  in  1934  to  0.12  percent  in  1935  to  0.16  percent  in  1936  and  to 
0.17  percent  in  1937,  while  the  franchise  tax,  measured  in  similar 
terms,  increased  oidy  from  0.07  percent  in  1934  to  0.10  percent  in 
1935  and  1936  to  O.l'l  percent  in  1937.^^ 

The  fixed-cost  taxes — the  property  tax  and  State  corporation  taxes 
(except  those  on  income) — are  markedly  regressive  in  at  least  two 
senses — they  are  relatively  heavier  on  small  business  and  lighter  on 
big  business  and  they  are  likewise  relatively  heavier  on  the  less 
profitable  enterprises  and  lighter  on  the  more  profitable  enterprises. 

"  See  appendix  D. 


CHAPTER  XI 
CONCLUSIONS 

The  tax  system  is  at  once  a  source  of  public  revenue  and  a  technique 
of  governance.  It  is  seldom  exclusively  one  or  the  other.  This  is  a 
fact  which  has  been  clearly  recognized  by  the  lawmakers  ever  since 
the  inauguration  of  the  Federal  constitutional  system.  The  tariff  is 
one  of  the  outstanding  examples  of  the  use  of  taxation  to  effectuate 
economic  policies,  i.  e.,  the  development  of  an  industrial  economy. 
The  enactment  of  the  Federal  corporation  excise  tax  in  1909  was  de- 
clared by  President  Taft  to  be  ^'a  long  step  toward  that  supervisory 
control  of  corporations  which  may  prevent  further  abuse  of  power." 
Other  examples  are  readily  available  in  American  tax  history. 

In  its  fiscal  aspects  the  tax  system  is  designed  to  raise  adequate 
revenues  for  the  great  public  heeds  without  harmful  consequences  to 
the  economy  as  a  whole  or  to  specific  sectors  of  it.  An  equally  im- 
portant desideratum  is  that  the  tax  system,  as  it  works  out,  should 
synchronously  mesh  with  the  broad  social  and  economic  policies  that 
have  been  democratically  accepted  by  the  Nation.  The  tax  system 
should  not  work  at  cross  purposes  with  the  objectives  of  the  commun- 
ity and  should,  moreover,  affirmatively  contribute  to  achieving  what- 
ever objectives  the  community  has  set  before  it,  whether  it  be  on 
Federal,  State,  or  local  levels. 

The  problems  of  taxation  are  therefore  not  exclusively  problems  of 
revenue — notwithstanding  the  traditional  maxim  that  ''taxation  for 
revenue  only"  is  best — but  are  also  problems  of  government  and  its 
relationship  to  economic  enterprise. 

Any  student  of  government  must  be  impressed  with  the  powerful 
tool  that  the  modern  state  possesses  in  its  tax  system.  The  taxing 
power  can  be  easily  demonstrated  to  have  many  advantages  over 
"ordering  and  forbidding  devices"  that  are  conventionally  employed 
by  the  police  state.  It  does  not  ordinarily  imply  a  vast  bureaucracy; 
it  leaves  the  specific  decisions  in  the  hands  of  private  entrepreneurs; 
it  is  largely  automatic  and  immediately  effective.  Its  sanctions  strike 
at  the  very  sinews  of  economic  power — the  payment  of  money.  The 
taxing  power,  however,  is  of  course  neither  the  exclusive  technique 
available  to  the  modern  state,  nor  one  suitable  for  all  ends  of  policy, 
but  it  is  one  that  must  be  skillfully  blended  with  all  the  other  powers 
and  instrumentalities  of  government  in  effectuating  common  objectives. 

It  is  hazardous  to  specify  in  detail  which  social  and  economic  ob- 
jectives the  Federal  Government  should  at  the  present  time  try  to 
achieve  through  the  exercise  of  its  taxing  powers.  The  prejudices  of 
personalities,  occupations,  and  sections  are  so  easily  nationalized. 
Yet  it  is  probably  possible  to  indicate  in  a  broad  way  a  few  specific 
objectives  that  have  been  sufficiently  accepted  by  the  American 
democracy  that  any  tax  system  which  runs  counter  to  such  objectives, 
is  subject  to  serious  criticism. 

115 


j^-j^g  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Paramount  among  these  nonfiscal  desiderata  of  a  ''good"  tax  system 
within  a  democratic  framework  are  the  following: 

(a)  The  discouragement  of  idleness,  whether  of  men,  machines,  or 
money,  and,  conversely,  the  encouragement  of  full  employment  and 
utilization  of  resources; 

(6)  The  preservation  of  opportunities,  e.  g.,  by  encouraging  small 
business ; 

(c)  The  curbing  of  m.onopoly  or  at  least  the  profitable  fruits  of 
m.onopoly,  possibly  including  the  sim.phfication  of  corporate  struc- 
tures and,  conversely,  the  check  of  holding  companies  and  related 
forms  of  intercorporate  affihation;  and 

(d)  The  support  of  persons  in  need  (in  addition  to  affirm.ative  action 
via  relief  and  social  security)  by  relieving  the  tax  burden  on  persons 
in  the  lowest  incom,e  brackets. 

These  social  and  economic  objectives  are  frequently  in  conflict  with 
fiscal  needs,  e.  g.,  the  sales  tax.  No  sim.ple  or  universal  formula 
can  be  drawn  up  and  applied.  It  is  always  necessary  to  strike  a 
series  of  balances  between  the  one  and  the  other. 

FEDERAL    CORPORATE    INCOME    TAXES    IN    GENERAL 

Corporate  profits  have  been  continuously  subject  to  Federal 
taxation  since  1909.  The  highest  effective  tax  rates  on  corporate 
incom.e  (tax  as  percent  of  legal  income)  occurred  during  the  war 
period  (1917  to  1920)  when  the  rates  ranged  as  high  as  37.8  percent, 
while  the  present  effective  tax  rate  (in  1937)  on  corporate  incom.e  is 
17.3  percent. 

The  catastrophic  decline  of  corporate  profits  during  the  great 
depression  caused  a  substantial  drop  in  the  yield  of  Federal  corj^orate 
incom.e  taxes.  The  subsecj[uent  improvement  of  business  conditions 
and  the  resurgence  of  corporate  profits  led  naturally  to  a  rise  in  the 
yield  of  Federal  corporate  incom.e  taxes.  In  the  downward  spiral  of 
the  depression  the  yield  of  Federal  taxes  declined  much  m.ore  pre- 
cipitously than  did  corporate  profits,  priro.ariiy  because  of  the  allow- 
ance for  prior  years'  losses  in  establishing  the  tax  base.  During  the 
recovery  period  the  yield  of  Federal  taxes  increased  more  rapidly  than 
did  corporate  profits,  reflecting  the  rise  in  statutory  rates.  But  the 
discrepancy  between  the  respective  rates  of  increase  of  taxes  and 
profits  was  substantially  less  than  that  which  existed  between  the 
rates  of  decline. 

In  1937  corporations,  after  paying  IK  billion  dollars  in  taxes  to  the 
Federal  Governm.ent,  distributed  8)2  billion  dollars  to  noncorporate 
investors  (stockholders  and  bondholders)  and  had  4K  bihion  dollars 
available  for  reinvestm.ent  or  industrial  replacement  (i.  e.,  profits 
after  taxes  and  dividends  plus  depreciation  and  depletion). 

Corporate  profits  were  reduced  relatively  less  by  taxes  and  dividend 
paym.ents  and  consequently  corporate  funds  available  for  reinvest- 
m.ent  were  relatively  larger  in  the  sm.aller  size  classes,  despite  the 
substantial  undistributed-profits  taxes  to  which  the  smaller  cor- 
porations were  subject  in  1936-37. 

The  Federal  corporate  tax  systems  contribute  nothing  to  the 
resolution  of  the  ''m.onopoly  problem.,"  since  ''monopoly  profits"  are 
taxed  in  the  same  way  and  at  the  same  rates  as  other  corporate 
profits. 


OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  H'J 

Creditor  or  debt  financing  is  at  present  encouraged  by  the  Federal 
tax  system  through  the  deductibihty  (and  consequent  exemption)  of 
ah  interest  paym.ents.  Since  dividends  distributed  are  not  deducted 
from  corporate  net  incom.e  for  Federal  tax  purposes,  and  interest  pay- 
m.ents  to  bondholders  are  so  deducted,  equity  financing  is  discriminated 
over  against  creditor  financing.  Bondholder  capital  is  don^inant  in 
public  utihties,  service,  and  financial  corporations  but  plays  a  relatively 
minor  role  in  m.anufacturing. 

Fluctuating  enterprise — which  is  largely  identified  with  small 
corporations  and  such  industries  as  mining,  construction,  and  forest 
products — is  discriminated  against  by  any  tax  system,  based  on  the 
economic  fortunes  of  a  single  year.  This  discrimination  was  sub- 
stantially avoided  prior  to  1931-32  and  will  largely  be  eliminated  in 
1940  when  tax-paying  corporations  will  again  be  permitted  to  carry 
over  operating  losses  (for  a  2-year  period). 

The  Federal  tax  system,  encourages  (a)  agiicultural  cooperatives 
(purchasing  and  m.arketing)  and  (6)  various  form.s  of  m.utuaJ  insurance 
companies  (other  than  life)  by  exem.pting  the  same  from  all  corporate 
incom.e  taxation,  (c)  Life-insurance  com.panies  benefit  from,  a  special 
deduction  of  all  investment  income  under  4  percent  of  legal  reserves, 
which  is  practically  tantam.ount  to  com,plete  tax  exemption  of  life- 
insurance  companies,  (d)  Operators  of  oil  and  gas  wells  benefit  from 
very  substantial  depletion  deductions  based  on  extraordmary  discovery 
values,  the  provision  for  which  was  introduced  by  the  War  Revenue 
Act,  when  the  opening  of  new  oil  and  gas  fields  was  essential  to  the 
prosecution  of  the  war,  and  has  been  retained,  in  the  revenue  law  in 
substantially  unaltered  form.,  long  after  the  passing  of  the  original 
need. 

NORMAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAX 

Small  corporations  (usually  defined  by  law  as  having  net  income 
under  $25,000)  were  substantially  favored  by  the  Federal  revenue  acts 
from.  1909  to  1912,  inclusive,  and  from.  1918  to  1931,  inclusive,  by  a 
statutory  exem.ption  of  the  initial  $2,000  to  $5,000  of  net  incom.e. 
The  repeal  of  this  exemption  at  the  very  nadir  of  the  depression  (1932) 
vaulted  the  effective  tax  rates  on  sm.all  corporations  by  fourfold  and 
fivefold . 

Sm.all  corporations  were  subject  to  the  same  statutory  rates  as  large 
corporations  from.  1932  to  1935,  inclusive.  The  special  credits  for 
investm.ent  incom.e  (i.  e.,  dividends  received  from,  domestic  corpora- 
tions and  interest  received  on  governm.ental  obligations)  have  been  of 
little  im.portance  to  the  sm.all  corporations  since  little  of  their  income 
is  derived  from  investm.ents.  Such  special  credits  for  investm.ent 
incom.e  have  been  of  considerable  unportance  to  the  large  corporations. 

Sm.all  corporations  have  been  somewhat  favored  by  the  Federal 
revenue  acts  of  1936  and  subsequent  years  through  the  introduction 
into  the  corporate  incom.e-tax  system  of  a  slightly  graduated  rate 
structure,  based  on  the  m.agnitude  of  net  incom.e.  Available  data  for 
1936-37  indicate  that  the  graduated  rate  structure  does  not  favor 
small  corporations  to  the  substantial  extent  noted  in  the  case  of  the 
statutory  exem.ption  cited  in  paragraph  9.  The  revenue  acts  of  1938 
and  1939  narrowed  the  range  of  the  rate  graduation,  which  was 
already  very  slight,  so  that  the  favoritism,  shown  sm.all  corporations 

262698— 41— No.  9 9 


llg  OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

ill  1938  and  1939  is  probably  less  than  that  found  for  1936  and  1937.. 
As  a  consequence  of  the  second  Revenue  Act  of  1940  the  range  in 
rates  has  again  been  increased,  but  it  still  remains  substantially  lesa 
than  in  the  period  prior  to  1932. 

Between  1917  and  1933,  inclusive,  the  Federal  revenue  acts  per- 
mitted the  filing  of  consolidated  corporate  income-tax  returns  in  which 
the  losses  of  individual  subsidiaries  were  deductible  from  the  profits 
of  other  m. embers  of  the  corporate  group.  This  device  substantially 
facilitated  the  continued  existence  and  rapid  growth  of  vast  networks 
of  interaffiliated  corporate  systems  and  pyramids  of  intertwined  hold- 
ing com.panies.  A  slight  tax  penalty  (at  the  rate  of  0.75  and  1  percent) 
was  im.posed  on  consolidated  returns  in  1932  and  1933.  Starting  in 
1934  only  railroads  and  related  common  carriers  have  been  perm.itted 
to  file  consolidated  corporate  incom.e-tax  returns. 

Except  for  the  period  from.  1913  to  1917,  inclusive,  intercorporate 
dividends  in  the  hands  of  the  recipient  corporation  have  been  sub- 
stantially exempt  from  Federal  taxation.  Between  March  1913  and 
1917  all  intercorporate  dividends  were  subject  to  taxation  in  the- 
hands  of  the  recipient  at  the  sam.e  statutory  rate  as  other  corporate 
income.  Starting  with  1936,  the  exemption  of  intercorporate  divi- 
dends has  been  limited  to  85  percent  of  the  sam.e,  which  is  equivalent 
(at  the  present  statutory  rate  of  24  percent)  to  a  tax  on  intercorporate 
dividends  at  the  rate  of  3.6  percent.  By  such  treatment  of  intercor- 
porate dividends,  the  Federal  tax  laws  obviously  do  httle  (at  present) 
or  have  done  nothing  (prior  to  1936)  to  hinder  the  widespread  and 
rapid  growth  of  holding  com.panies  and  related  forms  of  intercorporate- 
affiliation. 

Save  for  the  corporate  excise  tax  period  (1909  to  February  1913, 
inclusive)  corporate  investm.ents  in  the  securities  of  Federal,  State, 
and  local  governments  have  been  continuously  exempt  from  Federal 
tax. 

CAPITAL-STOCK    AND    EXCESS-PROFITS    TAXES 

The  Federal  capital-stock  tax  is  based  on  an  evaluation  of  capital 
in  term.s  of  corporate  earning  power  rather  than  in  terms  of  th& 
capital  actually  invested  or  tangible  net  worth.  The  present  ''excess- 
profits"  tax  is  nothing  m.ore  than  a  penalty  tax  on  those  corporations 
which  guess  badly  in  declaring  their  capital  stock  for  tax  purposes. 
Despite  its  name,  the  to,x  has  nothing  to  do  with  ''monopoly"  profits. 

The  com.pound  capital-stock  excess-profits  taxes  discriminate 
m.arkedly  against  corporate  enterprises  with  fluctuating  profits,  in- 
cluding small  corporations  and  corporations  in  particular  industries 
the  profits  of  which  cannot  be  accurately  forecast.  The  excess-profits 
tax  is  substantially  nonexistent  on  m.ost  large  corporations. 

UNDISTRIBUTED-PROFITS    TAX 

The  undistributed-profits  tax,  as  enacted  by  Congress,  was  designed 
to  (a)  remove  existing  tax  inequahtics  arising  out  of  the  nondistribu- 
tion  of  corporate  profits  and  the  consequent  avoidance  of  individual 
surtaxes  and  (b)  reduce  corporate  savings  and  thus  prevent  circum- 
vention of  the  capitol  market  with  respect  to  industrial  expansion. 
The  tax  probably  achieved  these  twin  objectives  to  some  extent,  but, 
in  so  doing,  entailed  several  undesirable  consequences  (the  principal 
of  which  are  cited  in  the  following  paragraph). 


1 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         219 

The  undistributed-profits  tax  of  1936  tended  to  fall  on  small-  and 
medium-sized  corporations  without  adequate  allowance  for  the  length 
of  the  accounting  period,  the  pressing  debt  structure  of  individual 
concerns,  and  the  differential  accessibility  to  the  capital  market. 

By  applying  to  all  corporate  income  (including  intercorporate 
dividends)  except  interest  received  on  governmental  obhgations,  the 
undistributed  profits  did  operate  som.ewhat  to  hinder  holding  com- 
panies and  other  form,s  of  intercoi-porate  affiliation. 

The  most  profitable  corporations  tended  to  report  higher  undis- 
tributed-profits tax  paj^m.ents  and,  to  this  extent,  the  surtax 
tended  to  curb  monopoly  profits,  except  in  the  case  of  the  largest 
corporations  distributing  m.ost  their  profits  since  they  had  ready 
access  to  the  capital  m.arket.  The  tax  was  hardly  an  attack  on 
existing  ''monopolies,"  but,  if  retained,  it  probably  would  have  con- 
stituted a  partial  check  to  potential  ''m.onopolies,''  the  sheer  growth, 
of  which  from  internal  sources  would  have  been  made  m.ore  difficult. 

Under  the  revisions  of  the  midistributed-profits  tax  by  the  1938 
Revenue  Act,  sm.all  enterprise  (i.  e.,  corporations  with  net  incom.e 
under  $25,000)  was  com.pletely  exempted,  special  deductions  for  debt 
retirem.ent  were  broadened,  the  cany-over  of  prior  year's  losses  was 
introduced,  and  noncash  distributions  of  corporate  profits  (i.  e.,. 
consent  dividends,  etc.)  were  permitted  on  a  larger  scale.  These  im,- 
provements  of  the  technical  character  of  the  tax  were  rendered  in- 
effective by  the  substantive  emasculation  of  the  rate  provision,  which 
defeated  the  objectives  of  the  tax.  The  repeal  of  the  rem.aining- 
stum.p  of  the  undistributed-profits  tax  by  the  Revenue  Act  of  1939 
essentially  left  the  tax  problem  where  it  was  before  the  enactm.ent  of 
the  1936  Revenue  Act,  except  for  the  em.otional  connotation  of  the 
phrase  ''undistributed -profits  tax." 

PAY-ROLL    TAXES 

The  social-security  taxes  on  pay  rolls  fall  relatively  lightly  on 
highly  m.echanized  enterprises  and  industries  and  relativel}^  heavily 
on  enterprises  and  industries  employing  labor  to  a  substantial  extent. 
This  differential  arises  out  of  the  selection  of  pay  rolls  as  the  tax 
basis,  which  is  only  one  among  several  cost  factors. 

Sm.all  enterprise  is  somewhat  favored  under  the  pay-roll  tax 
through  the  omission  from,  the  tax  base  of  the  cost  of  all  entrepre- 
neurial labor. 

As  other  cost  taxes,  the  pay-roll  tax  is  "regressive"  in  the  sense  that 
it  constitutes  a  relatively  larger  share  of  business  costs  in  the  case  of 
the  less  profitable  enterprises  than  in  the  case  of  the  moi*e  profitable 
group.  The  pay-roll  tax  is  also  'regressive"  in  the  sense  that  it  m.ay^ 
in  whole,  or  in  part,  be  shifted  to  prices. 

OTHER  TAXES 

The  m.ajor  share  of  Federal  exise  taxes  are  imposed  on  hquor  and 
tobacco  industries.  In  other  industries  the  course  of  such  taxes  has 
been  very  erratic,  with  a  present  tendency  to  diminish  both  in  volume 
and  in  the  variety  of  industries  singled  out  for  taxation.  Such  excises 
are  of  course  "regressive"  in  the  m.ain  part  since  they  usually  enter 
into  prices. 


220  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

General  State  sales  taxes  are  presently  imposed  in  23  States,  a 
decline  of  4  States  from  the  peak  of  27  reached  in  1937.  Such  taxes 
are  probably  most  important  to  the  retailer,  since  the  producer  and 
intermediaries  are  not  usually  subject  to  the  tax.  Such  taxes  are 
''regressive"  in  the  sense  that  they  must  be  paid  by  profitable  and 
unprofitable  enterprises,  and  also  in  the  sense  that,  if  shifted  to  price, 
they  fall  on  the  consumer,  irrespective  of  his  income. 

The  property  tax  and  State  corporate  taxes  are  ''regressive"  in  the 
senses  that  they  are  heavier  (a)  on  smaller  enterprise  than  large  enter- 
prise and  (6)  on  less  profitable  corporations  than  on  the  highly  profit- 
able corporation. 

These  regressive  patterns  are  only  partially  oftset  by  income  taxes 
in  32  States. 


APPENDIX  A. 
WAR  EXCESS-PROFITS  TAXATION 

The  wartime  excess-profits  tax  was  designed  to  tax  at  steeply  gradu- 
ated rates  the  excess  of  net  income  over  a  presum.ed  ' 'normal  return" 
on  ''invested  capital",  while  the  war-profits  tax  aimed  at  recouping  on 
behalf  of  the  Government  exorbitant  and  costly  charges  for  war 
supplies  via  taxation  rather  than  through  shrewd  bargaining  which 
m.ay  be  very  time-consuming  (at  a  period  when  tim.e  was  obviously 
of  the  "essence").^  The  concepts  of  "net  income,"  "normal  return," 
and  "invested  capital"  obviously  presented  serious  prob]em.s  of  inter- 
pretation and  enforcem.ent,  although  it  may  well  be  that  these  admin- 
istrative difficulties  have  been  exaggerated.^ 

In  arriving  at  net  income  for  excess  profits  tax  purposes  the  tax- 
payer was  allowed  a  special  deduction  for  the  amortization  of  "build- 
ings, machinery,  equipment,  or  other  facilities  (including  vessels),  con- 
structed, erected,  installed,  or  acquired,  on  or  after  April  6,  1917,  for 
the  production  of  articles  contributing  to  the  prosecution  of  the  present 
war  *  *  *"  insofar  as  the  same  had  been  "borne  by  the  tax- 
payer." ^  The  amount  of  the  cost  to  be  amortized,  it  was  provided  by 
the  regulations,  was  the  "excess  of  the  unextinguished  or  unrecovered 
cost  of  the  property  over  its  maximum  value  (either  for  sale  or  for  use 
as  part  of  the  plant  or  equipment  of  a  going  business)  under  stable 
post-war  conditions.^ 

The  rate  of  "normal  return"  was  flexibly  defined  under  the  1917  act^ 
ranging  from  7  to  9  percent,  in  accordance  with  "the  average 
amount  of  the  annual  net  income  of  the  trade  or  business  during  the 
pre-war  period"  (1911-13).^  A  more  precise  definition  was  given  by 
the  1918  act  which,  rejecting  the  concept  of  pre-war  standards,  pro- 
vided that  all  net  income  in  excess  of  8  percent  of  "invested  capital" 
should  be  regarded  as  "excess  profits"  for  tax  purposes. 

A  more  difficult  problem,  however,  was  the  determination  of  "in- 
vested capital."  The  most  relevant  experience  at  the  time  was  dis- 
tinctly discouraging — State  regulation  of  public  utilities  frequently 

1  Even  prior  to  the  entry  of  the  United  States  into  the  World  War  on  April  6, 1917,  Congress  had  embarked 
upon  a  special  program  of  war  taxation  of  corporate  profits.  The  rate  of  the  corporate  income  tax  of  1916 
was  doubled,  raised  from  1  to  2  percent  and,  applicable  to  the  following  year  (1917),  was  again  doubled,  raised 
to  4  percent.  The  manufacturers  of  munitions  were  subjected  under  title  II  of  the  Revenue  Act  of  1916  to 
a  special  tax  of  121^^  percent  "upon  the  entire  net  profits  actually  received  or  accrued  for  said  year  from  the 
sale  or  disposition"  of  "gunpowder,  explosives,  cartridges,  projectiles,  firearms,  submarines,"  etc.  The 
yield  of  this  tax  was  very  disappointing,  amounting  to  $42,000,000,  largely  as  a  result  of  an  exceedingly  liberal 
allowance  (sec.  302  (f))  for  the  "amortization  of  the  value  of  buildings  and  machinery,  account  being  taken 
of  the  exceptional  depreciation  of  special  plants."  See  Regulation  39,  arts.  20-21.  Also  see  Commissioner 
of  Internal  Revenue,  Report  for  1917,  p.  195.  The  Revenue  Act  of  1916  (title  IV,  sec.  407)  also  introduced  a 
capital  stock  tax  at  the  rate  of  "50  cents  for  each  $1,000  of  the  capital  actually  invested  in  the  transaction  of 
its  business."    See  Regulation  38. 

2  Supported  by  information  obtained  from  Treasury  sources.  . 

3  Sec.  214  (a)  (9).  Of  course  the  amortization  deduction  should  not  include  "any  amount  otherwise  al- 
lowed   *    *    *    as  a  deduction  in  computing  net  income."  . 

*  Regulation  45,  art.  183.  See  Regulation  62  (under  the  1921  act) ,  art.  84  for  more  precise  definitions.  Some 
available  data  on  a  small  sam.ple  of  large  corporations  indicates  that  the  amount  of  amortization  finally  al- 
lowed was  approximately  one-tenthof  taxable  net  income.  The  amortization  provision  was  retained  by  the 
Revenue  Act  of  1921  (sec.  234  (a)  (8)),  and  continued  for  "any  taxable  year  ending  before  March  3,  1924  (if 
claim  therefor  was  made  at  the  time  of  filing  return  for  the  taxable  year  1918,  1919, 1920,  or  1921)."  _ 

«  Sec.  203.  For  method  of  determining  "normal  return"  for  corporations  without  pre-war  experience,  see 
sec.  204  of  the  1917  act  and  Regulation  41,  arts.  22-23. 

121 


222  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

ran  afoul  of  circular  difficulties  in  defining  value,  with  long  drawn-out 
controversies  in  many  courts.  Yet  the  problem  had  to  be  faced.  The 
initial  statutory  attempt  was  a  deceptively  simple  definition  of  ''in- 
vested capital"  consisting  of  three  parts:  ''(1)  actual  cash  paid  in,  (2) 
the  actual  cash  value  of  tangible  property  ^  paid  in  other  than  cash,  for 
stocks  and  shares  *  *  *  and  (3)  pPtid  in  or  earned  surplus  and 
undivided  profits  used  or  employed  in  the  business  *  *  *"^  A 
proviso  added  that  ''invested  capital"  may  also  include  (a)  the  actual 
cash  value  of  patents  and  copyrights  paid  in  for  stock  at  not  m^ore  than 
the  par  value  thereof,  (b)  bona  fide  payments  (in  cash  or  tangible 
property)  for  goodwill,  trade-marks,  trade  brands,  and  franchises  or, 
if  acquired  prior  to  March  3,  1917,  bona  fide  payments  of  the  same  in 
stock,  not  exceeding  20  percent  of  the  total  shares  of  stock.^  "In- 
vested capital"  specifically  did  not  include  borrowed  money  or  prop- 
erty or  any  assets  the  income  of  which  was  not  subject  to  the  excess- 
profits  tax.^ 

The  definition  of  "invested  capital"  was  som.ewhat  clarified  by  the 
Revenue  Act  of  1918,  although  the  statutory  phraseologj^  m.ay  super- 
ficioJly  appear  more  complex.  To  the  three  constituent  parts  of 
^•invested  capital"  were  added  intangible  property  bona  fide  paid  in 
for  stock  not  exceeding  (a)  25  percent  of  par  value  of  total  stock 
outstanding,  (b)  actual  cash  value  of  such  propert}^,  or  (c)  par  value 
of  the  stock  issued,  whichever  is  lower.  This  new  clause  superseded 
the  vague  "proviso"  of  the  1917  act  anent  specified  types  of  intangible 
property  and  the  strained  administrative  definition  of  "tangible" 
property.  The  new  regulations  under  the  1918  act  candidly  pointed 
out  that  "invested  capital"  had  no  relationship  to  "present  net  worth 
of  the  assets"  of  the  corporation  but  was  rather  based  on  "the  capital 
actually  paid  into  the  corporation  by  the  stockholders."  ^^ 

The  actual  operation  of  the  war  excess-profits  taxes  for  seven  major 
industries  is  shown  in  table  1  hereof,  for  the  5-year  period  (1917-21) 
during  which  the  tax  was  in  existence. ^^  The  peak  of  the  ratio  of 
the  excess-profits  tax  to  net  income  in  each  industry-  was  reached  in 
1918,  the  same  year  in  which  interindustry  difierences  were  gTcatest. 
Throughout  the  entire  5-year  period  the  highest  tax  ratio  was  for  the 
construction  industry  (47.8  percent)  with  m.anufacturing  (37.8 
percent)  a  close  second,  while  the  ratio  was  consistently  loAvest  for 
public  utilities  (8.6  percent)  and  finance  corporations  (8.9  percent). 
The  low  ratio  for  public  utilities  is  to  be  expected  in  view  of  their 
regulation  by  public  authorities  which,  if  effective,  cannot  tolerate 
excess  profits,  while  the  low  rate  for  finance  corporations  reflects  the 
low  but  steady  rate  of  return  on  investm.ent  characteristic  of  that 
industry.  Service  corporations  (15  percent)  tended  to  fall  in  the 
lower  group,  while  mining  (25.1  percent)  and  trade  (27.5  percent)  fell 
in  the  higher  gi'oup.  The  percent  in  brackets  indicates  the  1918  tax 
ratio  for  a  given  industry.  Among  the  manufacturing  industries  the 
highest  tax  ratios  appeared  for  textiles  and  m.etals — both  industries 
characteristically  playing  a  major  part  in  the  production  of  war 

6  By  re-^ulation  "tangible  property"  was  defined  to  include  stocks,  bonds,  bills  and  accounts  receivable, 
note^  and  other  evidences  of  indebtedness,  and  leaseholds.    Op.  cit.,  art.  47. 

»Sec.  207  (a). 

•See  arts,  fy^-f^b  of  Regulation  41 

» Sec. 207 

10  Regulations  45,  art.  831. 

"  No  data  are  available  for  manufacturinc  industries  for  1917.  The  1918  data  do  not  permit  a  separation 
of  the  war-profits  tax  payments  from  the  excess-profits  tax  payments;  the  importance  of  the  former  was 
largely  confined  to  industries  producing  military  supplies  purchased  by  the  Federal  Government. 


OONOENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER  123 

supplies.  The  ratios  for  the  other  manufacturing  industries  were 
fairly  similar  bo  one  another,  with  chem.icals  high  and  printing  low. 

One  of  the  fairly  simple  and  safe  methods  of  avoiding  the  war 
excess-profits  tax  was  for  the  corporations  to  expand  their  expendi- 
tures for  advertising,  establishment  of  branch  plants,  renovations 
and  repairs  of  existing  plant  and  equipment  (if  not  already  charged 
off  as  depreciation),  salary  boosts  for  executives,  and,  allegedly, 
depressed  prices  designed  to  build  goodwill.  But,  as  has  been  care- 
fully noted  by  one  observer,  these  techniques  of  avoidance  "were 
designed  to  postpone  the  yield  of  the  business  until  the  profits  tax  had 
been  abolished,  and  would  have  lost  their  efficiency  if  the  tax  had  been 
retained  indefinitely  at  stable  rates."  ^^ 

Despite  the  large  yield  of  the  excess-profits  taxes,  the  gradual  reso- 
lution of  the  initial  administrative  problems,  and  the  Presidential 
declaration  of  the  desired  permanency  of  the  principle  of  excess- 
profits  taxation  ^^  the  Treasury  and  Congress  grew  increasingly  critical. 
Carter  Glass  in  his  1919  report  as  Secretary  of  the  Treasury  castigated 
the  tax  as  follows: 

The  Treasurer's  objections  to  the  excess-profits  tax  even  as  a  war  expedient  (in 
contradistinction  to  a  war-profits  tax)  have  been  repeatedly  voiced  before  the 
committees  of  the  Congress.  Still  more  objectionable  is  the  operation  of  the 
excess-profits  tax  in  peacetimes.  It  encourages  wasteful  expenditure,  puts  a  pre- 
mium on  overcapitalization  and  a  penalty  on  brains,  energy,  and  enterprise,  dis- 
courages new  ventures,  and  confirms  old  ventures  in  their  monopolies.  In  many 
instances  it  acts  as  a  consumption  tax,  is  added  to  the  cost  of  production  upon 
which  profits  are  figured  in  determining  prices,  and  has  been,  and  will,  so  long 
as  it  is  maintained  upon  the  statute  books,  continue  to  be,  a  material  factor  in 
the  increased  cost  of  living. i* 

His  successor,  Secretary  Houston,  also  advocated  the  repeal  of  the 
tax,  urging  in  its  stead  a  flat  tax  on  ''profits  in  excess  of  the  distributed 
earnings"  of  corporations.  His  criticisms  may  be  summarized  in  the 
following  quotation: 

The  reasons  for  the  repeal  of  the  excess-profits  tax  should  be  convincing  even 
to  those  who  on  grounds  of  theory  or  general  political  philosophy  are  in  favor  of 
taxes  of  this  nature.  The  tax  does  not  attain  in  practice  the  theoretical  end  at 
which  it  aims.  It  discriminates  against  conservatively  financed  corporations  and 
in  favor  of  those  whose  capitalization  is  exaggerated;  indeed,  many  overcapital- 
ized corporations  escape  with  unduly  small  contributions.  It  is  exceedingly  com- 
plex in  its  application  and  difficult  of  administration,  despite  the  fact  that  it  is 
limited  to  one  class  of  business  concerns — corporations.  Moreover,  it  is  rapidly 
losing  its  productivity.  The  invested  capital  of  the  average  corporation,  earning 
profits  high  enough  to  subject  it  to  the  excess-profits  tax,  is  now  estimated  to  be 
increasing  at  the  approximate  rate  of  12  percent  a  year,  while  the  income  of  the 
average  corporation  is  almost  certainly  declining  at  as  great  a  rate.  Both  move- 
ments cut  into  the  productivity  of  the  tax.  If  the  present  changes  in  capital  and 
income  continue  for  some  time  in  the  future,  as  now  seems  probable,  a  large  reduc- 
tion may  be  expected  in  the  yield  of  the  excess-profits  tax.  For  the  present  fiscal 
year,  the  profits  tax,  with  collections  of  back  taxes,  is  estimated  to  yield  about 
$1,250,000,000,  and  for  the  fiscal  year  1922  about  $800,000,000,  as  against  an 
estimated  yield  for  the  fiscal  year  1920  of  slightly  over  $2,000,000,000.15 

12  R.  M.  Boeckel,  Taxation  of  Excess  Profits,  Editorial  Research  Reports  (1933),  II:  73.  For  a  critical 
review  of  the  role  of  taxation  in  controlling  wartime  profits,  see  the  report  of  the  Special  Committee  on 
Investigation  of  the  Munitions  Industry  on  Wartime  Taxation  and  Price  Control  (74th  Cong.,  1st  sess., 
Report  No.  944,  pt.  2). 

13  This  declaration  was  made  as  late  as  May  20,  1919,  in  his  first  message  to  the  special  session  of  the  66tn 
Congress.  Conceding  that  the  "excess-profits  tax  need  not  long  be  maintained  at  the  rates  which  were  neces- 
sary while  the  enormous  expenses  of  the  war  had  to  be  borne,"  the  President  urged  that  the  tax  "should  be 
made  the  basis  of  a  permanent  system  which  will  reach  undue  profits  without  discouraging  the  enterprise 
and  activity  of  our  businessmen." 

1^  Pp.  23-24. 
i«  Pp.  38-39. 


]^24  OONCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

On  the  other  hand,  David  Friday  wrote  in  his  study  of  profits, 
wages,  and.  prices: 

If  we  are  seeking  taxes  which  will  leave  the  income  of  the  masses  undisturbed, 
and  at  the  same  time  discourage  industry  and  enterprise  least,  our  present  excess- 
profits  taxes  are  founded  upon  the  correct  principle.  Tax  only  him  who  receives 
m-ore  income  than  is  necessary  to  call  forth  the  productive  service  which  he  renders; 
he  will  not  be  discouraged.  Do  not  levy  heavy  taxes  upon  the  property  or  income 
of  those  who  are  already  laboring  under  financial  difficulties  because  of  insufficient 
earnings;  discouragement  in  that  quarter  is  easy.  Modern  industry,  with  its  fluc- 
tuating markets,  its  ever-changing  technique,  its  unstable  price  level,  and  its 
sensitiveness  to  war  and  rumors  of  war  is  sufficiently  risky  without  increasing 
that  risk  by  subjecting  the  businessman  to  taxes  when  his  income  is  already 
inadequate.i^ 

Unfortunately  sufficient  data  are  not  at  hand  to  reach  a  considered 
judgment.  For  example,  the  Treasury  figures  on  collections  do  not 
segregate  any  of  the  war-income  taxes  on  corporations  and  natural 
persons  but  lump  them  in  a  single  figure  for  the  entire  war  period. 
There  are  no  figures  on  invested  capital  for  1918 — although  there  are 
such  figures  for  1917  and  1919-21.  Refunds  are  alleged  to  have  been 
very  large,  but  precise  data  are  again  lacking.^"^ 

19  P.  190. 

»'  See  footnote  2. 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWBK 


125 


z°^ 


OfOiOQCi»>OiOOOiOu:>(MlMOOO<»00(N^OOrHM>Oe<5'4<i-i005'C(NO        i-l 


cDOioot^'ffla>t>.rtOoai-^ooocot^t--a>coo5a5iM(M(X)COcococoO'^ 


OS. 


05IM03COOOO'^OOOCCt^C^'^CO»005«OOTt<CO'— I'O'O.-lOOl.-lOlOOO 

oiT^^-^c>Qd^^t>oicd■<^^^-^oo6«0(^^o>co>Ol©TJ^•<*^cocdo^"^t»o6cOl--io5 

I-HC^OleO'— Ir-lT-li-Hi-li-Hi— IrH  .-Hi— Ir-Hi— iC^  C^  1-1 


.-lO»Ct^<MC0-^OC0(M.-ic0-*05C!i0irHa>'*<M00iM(N00t^t^.-l01C^00 


l?q<N(N<Mrt.-(rt(NI>)iM(N. 


0-*CO-^r-H;CC50C005'*i03CO.-(CO(MaiTt<(NCi(N<»(N<NOOOC^<Mt^' 


CO   B 
C3   O 


(NC^lMCO<N<N<Me^(M(MIM. 


.-it^'Oooooooo-^coooa>oot^ooococ^.-icocoocOi-HC<5oaiTt<Tt<-*i(M 
^n'o5r-i'0^-;csi^^(:DOododfcc^-^TJJld■^■^oi(Nco^-:coT)^co^-;^>^c^"odt^ 


<CC»OCOCOCCCO<MTtlCOTfiCO-*<MCOCOlMiO. 


05  O  Ir^  00 


iO»Ol~->O00t^COO50it^C0-*i-«tiiO00iOr-lOC01^f0C0-"*i(NcO'O00'OeO-*i 


(x5co^^o6ooo6t>^Q6o6o6o6o6^-;oooc^-^^-^^-^05C»a>«5ojojo5^^^^0l6od 


OOt-.iOT»<^CC(M'«*<(NOOO>00001>-'-it^lMOCOIMMOIMCOCCCOe^iO 


C0OiOiOiO'O'-lTt<00O00t^C0OG0'-i(NC0t^t^'O-*O01C<IO«30000(M 

^-:odtdo6Gdo6<x5(X3^-:o6«o6^>:oo6o6c»<»oO'-HOrtr-^■rt0^^^cdoo 


CO  »0  00  <N -^  CC  t^  •-H  t^  iC  00  <M  O -^  i-H  •*  O  OS  i-H  lO  lO  05  00  <£)  ^  C<l  CO  rt<  Oi  ■*        Ci 

CO  CO  CO  CO  o  o  o  b^  CO  >-< -"^  ■-<  .-H  o  >--<  1-H  Tt' ■>#  o  i-i -^  •^  Tj5  ^-I  e^  irj  T^  »o  o 


O  M  00 -^  ■*  CO  CO  05  t^  <0  m  00  0>  05  O)  O -^  05  00  U3  »0  CO  »-i  o  ■*  t^  o>  ?D  •^  O       lO 


-O  o 
c/;  o 


OCOC~5f0  05'^C5>000<OCOCOt^t^OOOO'-H'*OicDCO»OCOCO'«f-<*lCOI^C>1         CO 


00  C<1  O  CO  CO  to  t--.  O  O  00  ■— I  ■— I  ■*  00  IM  "O  O  00  CO  Oi  IC  IM  .-<  i-H  00  05  CO  CO  CD  o    o 

.-H  CO 


COO>CCO 


B8 


la 


OT3  -5~ 
^  c  X  ca 


as 


03  C3 


IT) 
I  3    ; 

!-e  S  r,  S  fl 


S^x: 


-2  a 

73  '?S^ 


^  I 


I'rf  o  ^ 
!  03  O  '-' 


CO    03  ., 

>  >  <D 

(S  03  p 

c  a  h 


APPENDIX  B 

FEDERAL    CAPITAL    STOCK    AND    EXCESS-PROFITS    TAXES 

1.  Derivation  oj  the  jormula  for  calculating  the  interlocking  effective 
rates  oj  the  capital  stock  and  excess-'profits  taxes} — The  problem:  To 
find  the  total  tax  payments  of  the  capital-stock  tax  and  the  excess- 
profits  tax,  measured  as  percentages  of  taxable  net  income,  under 
alternative  declarations  of  capital  (as  times  net  income). 

I.  Definitions: 

(7=  declared  capital  (stated  in  dollars) 
(72"=  capital  tax  (stated  as  a  decimal) 

£'=  excess-profits  tax  (stated  as  a  decimal) 

A^— net  income  (stated  in  dollars) 
^7^=  total  tax  (percentage  of  net  income) 

Since,  by  law,  no  excess-profits  tax  is  payable  whenever  N  is  equal 
to  or  less  than  O.IOC,  and  since  the  rate  of  the  excess-profits  tax  shifts 
as  the  relationship  between  A^  and  C  changes,  it  is  advisable  to  work 
with  three  different  formulae,  each  applicable  to  one  of  the  three  pos- 
sible assumptions. 

II.  Formulae  to  be  used  in  computing  TT: 

A.  When  A^is  less  than  or  equal  to  0.10(7,  no  excess-profits  tax  is 
payable  (case  I). 

TT,  =  CT=OmiC  (1) 

B.  When  N  is  greater  than  0.10(7  but  equal  to  or  less  than  0.15(7 

TT2^CT-{-E2^ 
where 

£-2=0.06  [N-OAQC] 
.•.1^2=0.001(7+0.06  [A^-0.10(7] 

=  0.067V-0.005(7  (2) 

C.  When  A^  is  greater  than  0.15(7 

rT3=(7r+£'3  where 
£:3=0.06  [(A^-0.10(7)-(A^-0.15C)]  +  0.12  (A^-0.1560 
=  0.06  (0.05)(7+0.12(A^-0.15O) 
=  0.12A^-0.015(7 
.-.  rT3=0.00lC+0.12A^-0.015(7 

=  0.12Ar-0.014(7  (3) 

III.  Relation  between  C  and  TT  for  a  given  value  of  N  (application 
of  the  formulae):  Assume  that  the  declared  capital  of  a  corporation 
is  X  times  its  net  income,  and  then  compute  the  total  tax  (as  a  per- 
centage of  net  income)  associated  with  values  of  X  ranging  from  0  to 
20. 


1  By  Orvis  A.  Schmidt,  Treasury  Department. 

2  The  subscript  2  is  here  applied  to  E  merely  to  keep  the  subscripts  the  same  throughtout  the  equation. 
There  is  thus  no  Ex. 

126 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  127 

Formula  (3)  must  be  applied  while 

A^>0.15C,  or  while 
X<6.7 

Formula  (2)  must  be  applied  while 

0.10(7<iV<0.15O  or  while 
10>X>6.7 

Formula  (1)  must  be  applied  when 

X>10. 
Applying  formula  (3): 

rr3=o.i2iV-o.oi4  (xn) 

X=0  =0.120iV 

2  0. 12iV-  .028A^=  0.092iV 

4  0.12A^-.056A^=0.064Ar 

6  0.12A^-.084.V=0.036A^ 

Applying  formula  (2): 

rr2=o.o6A"-o.oo5(ZiV) 

X=8    0.06A^-0.040A/^=0.020iV 
Applying  formula  (1)  thereafter  to  any  value  of  X: 

TT,  =  omi{XN) 

X=:10  =  0.010A' 

12  =  0.012A^ 
14  =  0.014A^ 
16  =  0.016A^ 
18  =  0.018A" 
20-:0.020A^ 


Summarizing 

the  results : 

Declared  capital  is  X    Total  tax  vvill  be  (as  a 

times 

income  where         percent  of  income) 

0                                     12.0 
2                                       9.2 
4                                       6.4 

TTs 

6                                       3.6 

TT2 

8                                       2.0 
10                                       1.0 

TTi 

12                                       1.2 
14                                       1.4 
16                                       1.6 
18                                       1.8 
20                                       2.0 

2. 

Method  of  estimating  the  > 

capital  stock  tax  from  StatisfAcs  of  Income 

data, 

1933-37.- 

-The  estimate  started  with  the  amount  of  net  mcome 

reported  for  corporations  of  varying  size  and  capitalized  it  at  12.5 
percent  for  the  years  1933-35  and  at  10  percent  for  1936-37.  The 
resulting  figure  ^  was  the  ideal  capitalization  that  should  have  been 
declared  in  order  to  minimize  taxes.  This  figure  was  deficient  in 
two  respects — (a)  corporations  underdeclaring  their  capitalization 
and   (b)    corporations  overdeclaring  their  capitalization.     The  first 

3  Tabulated  in  column  1  of  appendix  B,  table  1,  p.  285. 


128 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


deficiency  was  corrected  by  capitalizing  the  amount  of  the  excess- 
profits  tax  reported  for  corporations  of  varying  size — that  is,  the 
amount  of  the  excess-profits  tax  was  divided  by  6  for  1933-35  and  9 
for  1936-37  (the  midpoint  between  6  percent  and  12  percent)  and 
multiplied  by  100 — which  have  the  amount  of  ^'excess  profits.'^ 
This  figure  was  in  turn  multiplied  by  12.5  in  1933-35  and  by  10  in 
1936-37,  giving  the  amount  by  which  capital  was  undeclared  (tabu- 
lated in  column  2  of  appendix  B,  table  1).  Deducting  column  2 
from  column  1  gives  the  estimated  minimum  capitalization  (column 
3)  from  which  the  magnitude  of  the  capital-stock  tax  (column  4) 
was  calculated  at  the  rate  of  $1  per  $1,000  of  declared  capitalization. 
The  relative  magnitude  of  the  capital  stock  tax  is  measured  as  a 
percent  of  net  income  (column  5) . 

This  estimate  is  deficient  only  in  the  respect  that  it  does  not  allow 
for  overdeclaration  of  capital.  The  chances  are  that  the  smaller 
corporations  and  corporations  engaged  in  industries  characterized  by 
widely  fluctuating  profits  will  more  likely  err  in  this  respect,  and 
that  the  larger  corporations  are  not  apt  to  be  far  oft'  in  their  fore- 
casting of  profits.  In  view  of  the  wide  range  of  error  permissible  in 
overdeclaring  capital  (shown  in  text  diagram  IV-1)  without  serious 
tax  penalties,  it  is  difficult  to  believe  that  this  error  in  the  estimating 
technique  introduces  any  size  bias  into  the  estimated  capital-stock 
tax  figures,  except  possibly  a  slight  bias  in  favor  of  the  larger 
corporations. 


Table   1, — Calculated  capital-stock  tax  on  corporations  of  varying  size,   1933-37 

[In  millions] 


Size  classes  (assets  in  thousands) 


1 

2 

3 

4 

Ideal  cap- 
italization 

Deficient 

Estimated 

Estimated 

capital 

capital 

capital- 

declared 

declared 

stock  tax 

$508 

$90 

$418 

0.4 

506 

76 

430 

.4 

1,136 

145 

991 

1.0 

1,236 

134 

1,102 

1.1 

1,525 

155 

1,370 

1.4 

3.810 

258 

3,  552 

3.6 

1,863 

62 

1,801 

1.8 

4,452 

77 

4,375 

4.4 

8,470 

98 

8,372 

8.4 

873 

130 

743 

.7 

879 

94 

785 

.8 

1,756 

170 

1,586 

1.6 

1,842 

154 

1,688 

1.7 

2,238 

159 

2,079 

2.1 

5,824 

253 

5,571 

6.6 

2,898 

84 

2,814 

2.8 

6,830 

102 

6,728 

6.7 

10,  570 

75 

10, 495 

10.5 

918 

180 

738 

.7 

952 

176 

776 

.8 

2,138 

332 

1,706 

1.7 

2,  250 

340 

1,910 

1.9 

2,722 

372 

2,350 

2.3 

7.  320 

880 

6,440 

6.4 

3.290 

191 

3,199 

3.2 

8,  520 

549 

7,971 

8.0 

11,910  1 

909 

11,009 

11.0 

Capital- 
stock  tax 
as  percent 
of  net  in- 
come 


1933 

Under  .$50. 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500- 

$500  to  $1,000 

$J,000  to  $5,000 -. 

$5,000  fo  $10,000. 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

Over  $50,000 

1934 

Under  $50 

$50  to  $100--. 

$100  to  $250. 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

$10,000  to  $.50,000- 

Over  $50,000 

1935 

Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250... 

$2,Wto$500 

$500  to  $1,000... 

$1,000  to  $5,000.. 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

$10,000  to  $50,000. 

Over  $50,000. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


129 


Table  1. — Calculated  capital-stock  tax  on  corporations  of  varying  size,  1933-37 — 

Continued 


[In  millions] 


Size  classes  (assets  in  thousands) 

1 

Ideal  cap- 
italization 

2 

Deficient 
capital 
declared 

3 

Estimated 
capital 
declared 

4 

Estimated 
capital- 
stock  tax 

5 

Capital- 
stock  tax 
as  percent 
of  net  in- 
come 

1936 
Under  $50 

1,496 
1,554 
3,543 
3,790 
4,611 

12,  671 
5,893 

13,980 
5,  925 

17,092 

1,414 
1,434 
3,311 
3,534 
4,198 

12,  242 
5, 377 

14,  795 
6,387 

20,518 

222 
186 
319 
263 
267 
560 
183 
157 
52 
74 

271 
232 
452 
418 
373 
1,075 
372 
810 
141 
376 

1,274 
1,368 
3,224 
3,587 
4,344 

12,111 
5,  710 

13,  823 
5,873 

17,018 

1,143 
1,202 
2,859 
3,116 
3,825 

11,167 
5,005 

13. 985 
6,246 

20, 142 

1.3 
1.4 
3.2 
3.6 
4.3 

12.1 
5.7 

13.8 
5.9 

17.0 

1.1 
1.2 
2.9 
3.1 
3.8 

11.2 
5.0 

14.0 
6.2 

20.1 

.9 

.9 
.9 
1.0 
.9 
1.0 
1.0 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500  .     - 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

1  0 

Over  $100,000 

1  0 

1937 
Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

1 

8 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

g 

$500  to  $1,000.. 

9' 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

Qi 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

9' 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

0' 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

^ 

Over  $100,000 

() 

Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 


APPENDIX  C 

OLIPHANT'S  STATEMENT  ON  HISTORY  OF  UNDISTRIBUTED 
PROFITS  PROBLEM 

Brief  History  of  Treatment  of  Business  Income  and  of  Attempts 
to  Prevent  the  Escape  of  Taxes  Through  the  Retention  of  Corporation 
Earnings  (statement  submitted  by  Herman  OKphant,  general  counsel 
of  the  Treasury  Department,  to  the  House  Ways  and  Means  Com- 
mittee) . 

An  act  of  Congress  passed  June  30,  1864,  provided  that  the  gains  and  profits 
of  corporations  should  be  inchided  in  the  annual  gains,  profits,  or  income  of  any 
person  entitled  to  the  same,  whether  divided  or  otherwise. 

With  the  advent  of  the  modern  income  taxes  in  1913,  a  provision  to  prevent 
the  evasion  of  surtaxes  through  the  use  of  corporations  was  introduced  in  the 
1913  act,  and  was  continued  without  substantial  change  in  the  Revenue  Acts  of 
1916  and  1918.  These  acts  provided  for  an  addition  to  the  dividend  income  of 
the  stockholders  of  a  corporation  which,  for  the  purpose  of  evading  surtaxes,  accu- 
mulated profits  beyond  the  reasonable  needs  of  the  business,  and  the  taxes  of  the 
stockholders  werethus  determined  as  if  distribution  had  actually  been  made. 

Shortly  before  and  while  the  Revenue  Act  of  1921  was  under  consideration,  the 
problem  received  much  attention  in  Congress,  by  the  Treasury,  and  by  repre- 
sentatives of  organized  business.  At  that  time  the  repeal  of  the  excess-profits 
tax  was  being  considered  and  the  opinion  was  w^idely  held  that  some  measure 
should  be  adopted  to  maintain  the  substantial  balance  which  had  existed  during 
the  period  of  the  war  taxes  when  individual  and  corporate  business  enterprises 
alike  were  taxed  at  high  rates. 

Secretary  Houston  in  his  annual  report  for  the  year  1920  recommended  sub- 
stituting for  the  then  existing  graduated  rates,  a  flat  tax  on  profits  in  excess  of 
distributed  earnings.  The  object  of  this  proposal,  he  said,  was  "to  establish,  so 
far  a.s  possible,  an  exact  equivalence  between  the  taxation  of  corporation  stock- 
holders and  other  taxpayers." 

So  eminent  an  authority  as  the  late  Dr.  T.  S.  Adams,  former  chairman  of  the 
Advisory  Tax  Board  in  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue  and  for  many  years  a 
Treasury  adviser,  as  early  as  1918  went  on  record  in  favor  of  the  taxation  of  un- 
divided profits  at  the  rates  which  would  apply  if  such  profits  were  distributed 
to  the  shareholders.  "Fiscal  necessity — and,  personally,  I  believe,  logic  as  Vv'ell," 
said  Dr.  Adams,  "requires  the  taxation  of  all  profits,  whether  reinvested  or  not." 
The  same  thought  was  behind  his  recommendation  in  1920  to  the  second  national 
industrial  tax  conference  that  the  corporation  income  tax  be  raised  from  10  to  16 
percent,  and  his  proposal  in  substance  became  a  part  of  the  majority  report  of  the 
conference  board's  tax  committee. 

Before  the  Senate  Committee  on  Finance  in  the  first  session  of  the  Sixty-seventh 
Congress,  the  National  Association  of  Credit  Men  proposed  that  there  should  be 
no  tax  upon  corporation  income  that  is  distributed,  and  opposed  the  flat  corpora- 
tion tax  on  the  ground  that  it  discriminated  against  small  shareholders  and  violated 
the  principle  of  taxing  the  individual  in  accordance  with  ability  to  pay.  A  similar 
proposal  was  made  to  the  same  committee  by  Mr.  Frank  H.  Seidman,  a  leading 
accountant  and  tax  expert  of  New  York,  Chicago,  and  Grand  Rapids,  and  Senator 
Jones  of  New  Mexico  introduced  an  amendment  to  the  1921  tax  bill  substantially 
along  the  lines  recommended  by  the  Association  of  Retail  Credit  Men.  As  finally 
enacted,  the  Revenue  Act  of  1921  contained  only  a  flat  tax  on  corporation  income 
at  the  low  rate  of  10  percent  for  the  year  1921  and  12^  percent  for  succeeding 
years,  while  the  maximum  individual  surtax  continued  through  1921  at  65  percent 
and  thereafter  at  50  percent. 

However,  Congress  recognized  that  the  importance  of  the  problem  called  for 
some  kind  of  legislative  action.     The  result  was  section  220  of  the  Revenue  Act 

130 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13][ 

of  1921,  which  imposed  a  surtax  of  25  percent  on  any  corporation  "formed"  or 
availed  of  for  the  purpose  of  preventing  the  imposition  of  the  surtax  upon  its  share- 
holders. In  1924  the  rate  of  tax  was  increased  to  50  percent,  which  rate  was  con- 
tinued in  the  law  until  the  Revenue  Act  of  1934,  Section  102  of  the  Revenue  Act 
of  1934  is  substantially  the  same  as  the  earlier  sections,  except  that  the  rate  of  tax 
is  reduced  to  25  percent  and  the  tax  is  levied  on  net  income  less  dividends 
and  taxes  paid  out  rather  than  on  the  entire  net  income. 

In  1926-27  the  Joint  Committee  on  Internal  Revenue  Taxation  made  a  careful 
study  of  the  problem  from  the  point  of  view  of  our  experience  and  that  in  Great 
Britain,  but  failed  to  recommend  a  tax  on  undivided  profits  because  of  the  fear 
that  it  might  cause  "unwise  distributions  and  prevent  the  accumulation  of  a  reason- 
able and  proper  surplus."  It  recomm-ended  instead  the  granting  of  a  deduction 
to  encourage  distribution  of  unneeded  surplus.  The  committee,  however,  ap- 
parently was  influenced  by  the  fact  that  at  that  time  the  maximum  individual 
surtax  rate  was  only  20  percent,  while  the  corporation  rate  was  13>^  percent. 

The  measures  adopted  by  Congress  to  prevent  evasion  of  the  surtaxes  proved  to 
be  difficult  to  administer  and  were  generally  ineffective.  This  led  Congress  to 
the  1934  act  to  impose  a  straight  tax  on  personal  holding  companies,  which  were 
among  the  worst  offenders,  in  which  no  proof  of  intention  to  evade  was  required. 
These  companies  are  now  taxed  on  their  undistributed  earnings  in  excess  of 
20  percent  at  rates  running  up  to  60  percent  on  amounts  in  excess  of  $1,000,000. 

In  the  1932  act  the  surtaxes  were  increased  to  35  percent,  while  the  flat  cor- 
poration rate  was  raised  only  to  13^4  percent.  This  disparity  between  the  indi- 
vidual and  corporation  rates  brought  into  sharp  relief  the  fundamental  inequity 
of  our  treatmxent  of  individual  business  enterprises,  as  well  as  the  unfairness  to  the 
small  stockholder,  and  early  in  the  Roosevelt  administration  intensive  studies 
were  undertaken  by  the  Treasury,  vvhose  experts,  with  the  cooperation  of  outside 
consultants,  considered  the  problem  from  every  angle.  While  the  unusual  de- 
mands for  revenue  may  have  been  the  immediate  reason  for  the  President's 
proposal,  the  problem  itself  is  as  old  as  the  income  taxes  and  has  had  the  con- 
sideration of  some  of  the  ablest  students  of  taxation.  House  Ways  and  Means 
Committee,  Hearings  on  the  1936  Revenue  Act,  pp.  658-659. 


APPENDIX  D 


TAX    EXPERIENCE    OF    312    IDENTICAL    MANUFACTURING 
CORPORATIONS,  1934-37 

Part  1. — In  thousands  of  dollars 


1934 

1935 

1936 

1937 

Percent 
change 
1934-37 

Sales -.. 

$5.  820,  521 

1,  910,  998 

465,  761 

$6,  888,  226 

2,  244,  555 

708,  379 

$8,  281,  555 
2,  736,  239 
1,031,449 

$9,672,339 
3, 147,  285 
1,  088.  927 

66.18 

Gross  profits 

64.69 

133. 80 

Federal  income  taxes.  _  .     ...  ..  ....  ..- 

56,  363 

73, 148 

129,  469 

13,  359 

14,  125 
261,617 

19.  608 
13,  426 
140.  198 
66,  418 
8,537 

148,  589 
20,  009 
14,  072 

288,  549 
67,  695 
16,  470 

139,  826 
69,  564 
10,  612 

163. 63 

Capital-stock  tax..  .     .      . ...     .. 

9,520 
247,  038 

11,413 
245,  938 

47.82 

Federal  excises 

Pay-roll  taxes 

16.80 

4,923 

101,  928 

64,  909 

4,290 

8,012 

112,316 

64,640 

6,704 

234.  55 

State  sales  taxes 

37.18 

7.17 

State  corporation  taxes 

147.  37 

Total  taxes 

488,  971 

522,  171 

666,  757 

775,  386 

58.57 

Part  II. —  Taxes  as  percent  of  sales 

ASSETS  UNDER  $1,000,000 


1934 

1935 

1936 

1937 

Federal  income  taxes 

0.73 

0.68 

1.30 
.15 
.14 

5.61 
.24 
.14 
.69 
.41 
.11 

0.80 

Undistributed-profits  tax 

.09 

Capital-stock  tax ...  ..     ._ 

.10 
6.26 

.11 
6.04 

.11 

Federal  excises 

4.85 

Pay-roll  taxes. --     .  ... . 

.67 

State  income  taxes 

.05 

.87 
.57 
.11 

.06 
.73 

.47 
.12 

.09 

State  sales  taxes ......             ....      _  .      .             .      ... 

.66 

Property  taxes..     ..     . ...     .     .. .. 

.36 

State  corporation  taxes    ...... 

.08 

Total  taxes 

8.69 

8.21 

8.79 

7.71 

ASSETS  $1,000,000  TO  $5,000,000 


Federal  income  taxes  ..      .           .              ...                   ... . 

1.10 

1.33 

1.63 
.30 
.17 

2.21 
.31 
.14 
.28 
.58 
.07 

1.48 

Undistributed-profits  tax 

.24 

Capital-stock  tax    ....                                                      .      .    . 

.14 
2.73 

.14 
2.48 

.14 

Federal  excises 

2.16 

Pay-roll  taxes ..             .                                        ........ 

.84 

State  income  taxes 

.08 
.32 
.81 
.08 

.12 
.23 
.66 
.08 

.16 

State  sales  taxes .      .         . 

.27 

Property  taxes 

.57 

State  corporation  taxes .                .  .      .... 

.07 

Total  taxes 

5.26 

6.04 

5.69 

6.93 

132 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Part  II. —  Taxes  as  percent  of  saZes— Continued 

ASSETS  $5,000,000  TO  $10,000,000 


135 


1934 

1935 

1936 

1937 

Federal  income  taxes.-      _ .     ...  . 

0.65 

0.84 

1.28 
.26 
.14 

1.06 
.33 
.10 
.07 
.62 
.11 

1  21 

Undistributed-profits  tax 

23 

Capital-stock  tax 

.12 

.47 

.13 
1.04 

12 

Federal  excises 

72 

Pay-roll  taxes...  . ...  .  ... 

93 

State  income  taxes.   .  . 

.04 
.06 
.95 
.09 

.07 
.09 
.72 
.09 

u 

State  sales  taxes.  ..  .  .     

06 

Property  taxes .  . ...         

60 

State  corporation  taxes. .  

09 

Total  taxes .  .    .  . 

2.38 

2.98 

3.97 

4  07 

ASSETS  $10,000,000  TO  $50,000,000 


Federal  income  taxes . 

1.12 

1.15 

1.61 
.15 
.17 

1.01 
.26 
.19 
.04 
.73 
.15 

1  45 

Undistributed-profits  tax.. -  . .  .      _  . 

16 

Capital-stock  tax    .        .  .        .... 

.16 
3.00 

.16 
1.57 

15 

Federal  excises _  .  .     .           .      ..         .... 

1. 14 

Pay-roll  taxes ...     . 

80 

State  income  taxes .  ...  .....        .  _.    ..      ....  ...    .      .... 

.08 
.04 
1.01 
.07 

.12 
.03 

.88 
.11 

.18 

State  sales  tax...  .  ... . .......... 

05 

Property  taxes 

68 

State  corporation  taxes. .  . 

.  13 

Total  taxes 

5.48 

4.02 

4.31 

4.74 

ASSETS  $50,000,000  TO  $200,000,000 


Federal  income  taxes  . 

1.10 

1.07 

1.70 
.13 
.14 

2.62 
.22 
.16 
.45 
.70 
.04 

1  47 

Undistributed-profits  tax .  _  ..  .         ..      ...  . 

.17 

Capital-stock  tax..        ...        ........ 

.13 
2.57 

.16 
2.57 

.  13 

Federal  excises.. -  ...      .....  .  .      .  . 

2.70 

Pay-roll  taxes... ...  .  . .. .... 

.65 

State  income  taxes 

.08 
.04 
.95 
.04 

.12 
.04 

.82 
.05 

.  16 

State  sales  tax...      . .. .      ...... 

.06 

Property  taxes             .  . 

.61 

State  corporation  taxes..  .  ... .  ... 

.06 

Total  taxes 

4.91 

4.83 

6.16 

6  01 

■ 

ASSETS  OVER  $200,000,000 


Federal  income  taxes. -- .  . 

0.79 

1.01 

1.43 
.16 
.20 

5.36 
.22 
.16 

4.31 

1.00 
.14 

1.71 

Undistributed-profits  tax 

.26 

Capital-stock  tax.  _. ..  .  ...  ..      .....     .      . 

.20 
7.11 

.18 
6.23 

.17 

Federal  excises 

4.66 

Pay-roll  taxes... ...  ...      .      .  .    . 

.65 

State  income  taxes 

.09 
4.67 
1.38 

.10 

.11 
4.54 
1.16 

.14 

.19 

State  sales  tax. _  _._      .............      ...         .               .         ... 

3.88 

.89 

State  corporation  taxes.- .      . ... 

.15 

Total  taxes 

14.34 

13.37 

12.98 

12.56 

TOTAL 


Federal  income  taxes 

Undistributed-profits  tax. 

Capital-stock  tax 

Federal  excises 

Pay-roll  taxes 

State  income  taxes 

State  sales  tax 

Property  taxes 

State  corporation  taxes... 


Total  taxes. 


0.97 


.16 
4.24 


1.75 
1.12 
.07 


8.39 


1.06 


.17 
3.57 


.12 
1.63 


r.59 


1.56 
.16 
.17 

3.16 
.24 
.16 

1.69 
.80 
.10 


i.Qi 


1.54 
.21 
.15 

2.98 
.70 
.17 

1.45 
.72 
.11 


8.03 


262698 — 11 — No. 


■10 


APPENDIX  E 
SOURCES  AND  METHODOLOGY 


SECTION  I.    BUREAU    OF    INTERNAL    REVENUE    DATA 

1.  The  universe  studied. — The  size  and  industrial  data  on  the  opera- 
tion of  Federal  taxes  on  corporate  income  for  tlie  period  1926-37  have 
been  computed  from  the  published  Statistics  of  Income  and  unpub- 
lished tables  of  the  Sourcebook  of  the  statistical  section  of  the 
Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue.  Although  these  Treasury  compilations 
are  based  on  returns  from  all  existing  corporations  in  the  United 
States,  a  part  report  no  income  data  because  they  are  inactive  and 
others  fail  to  include  balance  sheets  (not  legally  required  in  their 
income-tax  returns).  The  first  group  of  corporations  has  been  ex- 
cluded from  the  study  because  it  includes  more  legal  frames,  while  the 
second  has  been  excluded  from  all  size  analyses  (but  not  from  the 
detailed  industrial  comparisons)  because  of  the  nature  of  the  size 
classification  which  is  based  on  assets  (a  balance  sheet  item).  The 
second  group  of  excluded  corporations  is  negligible  in  financial  signifi- 
cance, their  receipts,  net  income,  and  Federal  tax  payments  being 
approximately  5  percent  or  less  of  the  respective  totals  for  all 
corporations. 

This  study  has  been  largel}^  limited  to  corporations  pacing  Federal 
corporate  income  taxes.  The  study  is  still  based  on  a  universe  and 
not  a  sample,  although  it  has  shrunk  to  a  universe  of  all  net-income 
corporations  submitting  balance  sheets  (table  I). 

Table  I. — Number  of  corporations  filing  income-tax  returns 


Total 
filing 

Inactive 

Lacking: 
balance 
sheets 

Filin 

g  balance  sheets 

Years 

No  net 
income 

Net  in- 
come 

Total 

1931 

516,404 
508,  636 
504, 080 
528,  898 
533,  631 
530,  779 
529, 097 

56,  700 

56,  752 

57,  238 
59,  094 
56,  518 
51,922 
51,259 

78, 616 
39, 863 
58,  278 
59,178 
61,908 
63,  203 
60,  936 

237, 893 
318,  730 
287,  623 
275,  662 
262,130 
227,101 
237,  967 

143, 195 
73,  291 
100,941 
134,964 
153,075 
188,  553 
178,  935 

381,088 

1932. 

392, 021 

1933 

388,  564 

1934 . 

410,  626 

1935..._ 

415,  205 

1936 

415,654 

1937 

416,902 

Source:  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 

2.  The  period  covered  and  comparability  from  year  to  ifear. — The  size 
analysis  is  limited  to  the  7  3^ears  of  1931,  1932,  1933,  1934,  1935,  1936, 
and  1937 — the  only  years  for  which  size  tabulations  by  assets  are  now 
(June  1-940)  available.  Previous  to  1931  some  data  are  available  by 
size  of  taxable  income  or  deficits,  but  net  income  is  sucli  a  shifting 
criterion  of  size  as  to  malve  a  structural  study  of  taxation  meaningless. 
The  3  years  of  1931,  1932,  and  1933  are  not  strictly  comparable  with 
134 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER  235 

the  succeeding  3  3^ears  of  1934,  1935,  and  1936,  because  of  the  aboli- 
tion of  the  consolidated  returns  device  (except  for  railroads)  b}^  the 
1934  Revenue  Act.^  Likewise,  the  period  1926-27  is  not  entirely 
comparable  with  the  1928-31  period  (in  the  industrial  analysis)  be- 
cause of  the  tightening  of  the  affihation  requirements  for  consolidated 
returns  under  the  1928  Revenue  Act.  It  is  unfortunately  not  possible 
to  show  the  precise  effects  of  the  abolition  of  the  consolidated  returns 
device  upon  the  size  composition  of  different  industries,  since  no  size 
data  of  this  character  are  available.  By  the  nature  of  the  case — the 
requirement  of  separate  returns  for  each  corporation  instead  of  a  con- 
solidated return  for  a  group  of  affiliated  companies — the  change  must 
have  been  rather  significant.  The  number  of  corporations  in  the 
large  size  groups  where  the  consolidated  parent  subsidiaries  were 
classified  presumably  decreased,  while  the  number  of  corporations  in 
the  sm_all  and  medium-sized  groups  wdiere  the  separated  subsidiaries 
are  classifiable  presumably  increased.  This  reduction  in  the  large-size 
groups  may  have  been  partially  off'set  by  the  addition  to  the  uncon- 
solidated balance  sheet  of  the  parent  of  such  new  items  as  invested 
securities  (i.  e.,  issued  by  subsidiaries)  that  has  previously  been  rep- 
resented in  the  consolidated  balance  sheet  by  the  physical  assets  of 
subsidiaries. 

3.  Validity  of  the  data. — These  data  cannot  presume  to  greater 
validity  than  that  which  may  be  ascribed  to  the  source,  Statistics  of 
Income  and  the  unpublished  Sourcebook  of  the  statistical  section 
of  the  Bui'eau  of  Internal  Revenue,  both  of  vrhich  are  equally  valid. 
The  Sourcebook  serves  primarily  to  furnish  additional  balance 
sheet,  income,  and  tax  items  (a)  by  major  industrial  groups  crossed  by 
size  classes  and  (b)  by  more  detailed  industrial  groups  (v/ithout 
crossing  by  size  classes).  Since  Statistics  of  Income  are  largely 
compiled  from  unaudited  returns,  changes  made  after  audit  (which 
may  stretch  over  several  years  and,  in  a  few^  cases,  decades),  are 
accordingly^  not  reflected  in  the  statistics.  The  item.s  most  susceptible 
to  revision  are  naturally  the  amount  of  tax  liability,  and  incom^e  and 
deduction  items  upon  which  the  former  is  based.  These  revisions 
may  be  upward  or  downward.  No  adjustments  for  auditing  have 
been  found  possible  and  the  figures  have  therefore  been  accepted  at 
their  face  value. 

The  item  on  taxes  claimed  as  deductions  appears  to  be  very  imsatis- 
factory  in  certain  industries  characterized  b}^  heavy  Federal  or  State 
taxes  on  sales  or  gross  production — namely,  beverages,  tobacco, 
rubber,  petroleum  (and  therefore  chemicals  with  which  petroleum 
was  tabulated  for  the  size  series  before  1936).  Under  the  regulations 
of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue,  taxes  paid  by  corporations  to  a 
governmental  agency  (except  special  assessments),  during  the  year 
covered  by  the  income-tax  returns,  may  be  claimed  as  deductions  in 
three  ways — as  (a)  ''taxes  paid";  (6)  part  of  ''cost  of  goods  sold"; 
or  (c)  part  of  "cost  of  operations."  If  the  corporation  claims  the 
deduction  in  either  of  the  two  latter  ways,  it  is  not  possible  on  the 
basis  of  the  present  statistics  to  separate  it  from  cost  of  materials, 
wages,  etc.,  and  consequently  the  figures  on  "taxes  paid"  remain 
incomplete. 

1  For  specific  changes  in  the  industrial  classification  of  identical  corporations  in  1933  and  1934  resulting 
irom  the  abolition  of  the  consolidated  returns  see  Statistics  of  Income  for  1934,  pt.  II,  pp.  25-27. 


136         OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  major  changes  in  industrial  classifications  have  fortunately 
been  in  an  expanding  direction,  so  that  items  for  later  years  can 
usually  be  converted  into  com^parable  items  for  earlier  years;  this 
process,  of  course,  cannot  be  reversed.  Insofar  as  the  size  analysis 
is  concerned,  such  changed  in  industrial  classifications  are  relatively 
unimportant.  Statistics  of  Income  included  beverages  with  food  for 
1931  and  1932  but  thereafter  kept  them  separate.  Taking  into 
account  the  fact  that  1933  was  not  comparable  with  succeeding  years 
because  of  the  change  in  the  consolidated  returns  device  and  that  the 
eighteenth  amendment  had  just  been  repealed,  it  was  decided  to  add 
beverages  to  food  for  that  year  in  order  to  make  it  comparable  with 
data  for  1932  and  1931.  From  1934  onward,  however,  food  and 
beverages  have  been  kept  separate.  In  the  1936-37 statistics  clothing 
was  separated  from  textiles,  petroleum  from  chemicals,  and  motor 
vehicles  from  metals.  In  the  case  of  industrial  comparison,  however, 
considerable  caution  is  necessary  in  interpreting  the  results,  since 
practically  every  year  witnesses  changes  in  the  definition  of  industrial 
categories  and  in  the  industrial  classification  of  individual  firms. 

SECTION    II.    DUN    &    BRADSTREET    TAX    DATA 

Dun  &  Bradstreet  early  in  1939  sent  out  a  questionnaire  attached 
to  all  manufacturing,  retailing,  and  wholesaling  firms  in  the  country^ 
asking  for  the  dollar  amount  of  their  sales  and  various  types  of  taxes 
paid  in  1938..  These  returns  were  partially  analyzed  in  the  April, 
June,  and  August  issues  of  Dun's  Review.  Dun  &  Bradstreet  gra- 
ciously made  the  tax  work  sheets  available  to  the  Department  of 
Commerce  and  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee. 

SECTION     III.    DEPARTMENT     OF     COMMERCE     TAX     SURVEY     OF     MANU- 
FACTURING    AND     TRADE     CORPORATIONS     REGISTERED     UNDER     THE. 


In  September  1939  the  Department  of  Commerce  sent  out  a  ques- 
tionnaire (a  copy  of  which  is  attached  hereto)  to  all  manufacturing 
and  trade  companies  which,  as  of  June  30,  1939,  had  securities  fully 
listed  on  registered  securities  exchanges.  The  list  of  companies  was 
supplied  by  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission  and  is  identical 
with  the  firms  appearing  in  the  Commission's  Survey  of  American 
Listed  Corporations. 

The  companies  were  asked  to  report  their  taxes  for  the  last  5  years 
on  the  same  basis  as  that  used  in  their  annual  report  on  Form  10-K 
to  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission.  Most  of  the  corporations 
filed  the  tax  questionnaire  on  a  consolidated  basis,  comparable  with 
other  data  filed  with  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission.  These 
returns  are  as  a  whole  not  comparable  to  the  type  of  returns  given  in 
Statistics  of  Income,  which  have  been  on  an  unconsolidated  basis 
since  1934.  Taxes  reported  included  only  such  taxes  as  were  paid 
directly  to  a  governmental  body,  even  though  the  firm  might  be  billed 
for  other  taxes  by  a  seller.  The  classification  of  taxes  is  apparent  from 
the  attached  questionnaire.  Some  companies  reported  taxes  as 
estimated  for  the  year  in  question  while  others  reported  actual  pay- 
ments for  the  year.  Others  gave  the  payments  as  made  and  then  the 
adjustments  that  subsequently  took  place. 

2  Primarily  prepared  by  John  Copeland. 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  137 

According  to  the  instructions,  the  amount  of  taxes  should  coincide 
with  the  sum  of  ''the  taxes  classed  as  (1)  operating  expenses  and 
(2)  charges  on  net  income"  in  the  annual  report  on  Form  10-K  to  the 
Securities  and  Exchange  Commission.  If  they  did  not,  the  company- 
was  requested  to  give  a  reconciliation.  For  most  cases,  taxes  did  not 
agree  with  those  listed  for  the  firms  in  the  Survey  of  American  Listed 
Corporations,  and  some  returns  gave  no  reconciliation.  The  greatest 
number  of  discrepancies  arose  in  the  Federal  income-tax  item  because 
the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission  asks  for  ''provision  for" 
income  taxes.  Almost  without  exception,  the  companies  reported 
a  lower  payment  than  the  amount  set  aside  (except  in  the  case  of  the 
large  steel  companies,  which  gave  the  estimated  payments).  A 
further  discrepancy  arose  from  the  fact  that  the  Securities  and  Ex- 
change Commission  included  under  this  heading:  "Federal  taxes  on 
income,  excess  profits,  and  undistributed  earnmgs;  State  taxes  on 
income;  and  foreign  taxes  on  income." 

Total  taxes  were  usually  greater  than  the  amount  as  reported  to 
the  Commission.  A  number  of  explanatory  notes  showed  that  many 
taxes  had  been  included  in  other  operating  expenses.  Returns  which 
disagreed  with  the  figures  in  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commis- 
sion's publication  but  had  no  explanation  as  to  the  discrepancy  were 
still  assumed  to  be  correct  if  (a)  the  total  taxes  did  not  vary  by  more 
than  10  percent  of  the  amount  as  reported  to  the  Securities  and  Ex- 
change Commission,  (6)  the  discrepancy  could  be  accounted  for  by 
differences  in  the  income  tax,  or  (c)  by  the  fact  that  some  one  other 
tax  item  had  apparently  not  been  reported  as  a  tax.  For  example: 
Suppose  total  taxes  as  listed  in  the  Survey  of  American  Listed  Cor- 
porations for  companj^  A  were  $50,000  with  $15,000  of  this  allocated 
to  income  taxes.  Total  taxes  were  given  by  the  company  in  its  ques- 
tionnaire as  $60,000  and  mcome  taxes  in  all  categories  amounted  to 
$7,500.  This  means  that  there  is  a  sum  of  $17,500  in  excess  of  the 
tax  payments  as  revealed  by  Form  10-K.  Looking  at  the  break-down 
of  taxes,  we  see  that  property  taxes  are  about  $17,000.  The  return  is 
marked  correct  on  the  assumption  that  property  taxes  v/ere  not  sepa- 
rately reported  to  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission.  When 
this  test  was  applied,  very  few  returns  seemed  to  be  mcorrect. 

All  returns  had  to  be  examined  to  determine  whether  entries  (whether 
in  dollars  or  as  zero)  were  made  for  taxes  that  should  have  been  paid. 
Large  companies  doing  business  in  a  number  of  States  supposedly 
paid  taxes  under  all  the  headings,  except  perhaps  Federal  excises. 
In  the  case  of  smaller  firms.  State  taxes  that  should  have  been  paid 
were  checked  against  the  tax  system  of  the  home  office  as  outlined  in 
Tax  Systems  of  the  World. 

Taxes  included  m  the  "all  other"  category  were  often  identified 
more  specifically,  which  facilitated  their  being  placed  in  the  correct 
bracket  or  else  excluded.  Only  a  few  corporations  listed  large  amounts 
in  this  category  without  describing  the  payment. 

Taxes  recorded  but  excluded  in  editing  included  all  payments  to 
foreign  or  territorial  governments.  In  the  case  of  companies  doing  a 
large  foreign  business,  such  charges  amounted  to  a  large  proportion 
of  the  total  tax  bifi,  but  for  the  survey  as  a  whole  they  were  not 
significant.  To  mclude  foreign  taxes  would  have  been  impossible 
because  (a)  many  companies  which  reported  foreign  taxes  reported 
only  foreign  income  taxes,  and   (6)  some  of  the  companies  paying 


J38  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

substantial  sums  abroad  failed  to  report  them  because  they  assumed 
that  we  were  interested  only  in  United  States'  taxes.  Also  excluded 
were  income  taxes  paid  for  bondholders  under  tax-free  covenents. 
Although  paid  by  the  corporation  they  were  considered  not  tax 
payments  of  the  corporation,  but  in  the  nature  of  additional  mterest 
payments. 

The  entries  most  frequently  missing  were  the  Federal  excises  and 
State  sales  levies,  probably  because  they  are  so  often  passed  on  to  the 
buyer.  Processing  taxes  were  likewise  often  omitted.  Breweries, 
tobacco,  and  liquor  companies  made  fairly  complete  returns  on  these 
two  types  of  levies,  but  petroleum  refineries  almost  invariably  failed 
to  report  such  expenditures  or  else  combined  the  two  so  that  the  sum 
was  unusable.  Very  few  of  the  automobile  parts  companies  reported 
the  excises  on  their  products. 

Although  one  or  more  tax  items  may  have  been  incorrect,  the 
schedule  was  of  course  usable  insofar  as  the  specific  entries  were 
correct,  except  when  tabulating  "total  taxes."  Incomplete  question- 
naires could  be  used  by  tabulatmg  separately  the  economic  items 
(which  were  copied  from  the  Survey  of  American  Listed  Corporations) 
for  each  tax  item  that  was  correct.  For  example:  To  get  the  ratio 
of  income  taxes  to  net  before  interest,  only  cards  reporting  mcome 
taxes  correctly  would  be  tabulated  for  net  and  income  taxes.  Then 
the  ratio  would  be  calculated.  If  State  sales  taxes  as  a  percentage  of 
sales  were  desired,  only  cards  reporting  sales  taxes  correctly  would 
be  used;  for  the  relation  of  property  taxes  to  sales,  only  cards  having 
property  taxes  entered  correctly.  This  would  mean  that  there  would 
be  a  varymg  number  of  cases  used  in  the  calculation  of  each  ratio, 
because  not  all  of  the  same  cards  would  be  correctly  filled  in  for 
each  item. 

A  small  number  of  returns  were  unusable  because  taxes  were  reported 
for  the  parent  registrant  only,  while  the  economic  data  supplied  by 
the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission  covered  subsidiaries  as  well. 

The  computation  of  wages  for  the  purpose  of  estimatmg  ''gross 
margin"  presented  a  special  problem.  The  Social  Security  pay  roll 
and  unemployment  compensation  taxes  paid  were  used  m  the  calcula- 
tion. It  was  assumed  that  the  tax  payments  were  1  percent  of  wages 
in  1936,  3  percent  in  1937,  and  4  percent  m  1938  (the  1938  material 
was  calculated  to  check  the  1936  and  1937  figures).  The  payments 
as  reported  for  each  year  were  divided  by  the  appropriate  percentages 
and  the  resulting  quotients  multiplied  by  100.  This  product  was 
used  as  the  wage  bill  of  the  reporting  concerns. 

So  far  the  problem  seems  simple,  but  there  are  certain  complications. 
The  old-age  annuity  payment  was  1  percent  for  1937  and  1938.  The 
Federal  unemployment  compensation  levy  was  1  percent  in  1936, 
2  percent  in  1937,  and  3  percent  in  1938,  with  a  rebate  up  to  90  percent 
of  these  sums  of  the  amount  paid  by  a  company  to  a  State  unemploy- 
ment fund.  Thus  a  company  in  1936  paid  only  0.1  percent  to  the 
Federal  Government  if  there  was  a  State  system  in  which  the  rate 
was  at  least  0.9  percent.  No  company  could  pay  less  than  the  rates 
assumed,  but  there  was  a  chance  of  its  paying  more.  If  a  State  had 
a  rate  of  3  percent  in  1938,  the  company  would  pay  3.3  percent  because 
the  Federal  Government  rebated  only  90  percent  of  its  3  percent  rate 
or  2.7  percent.  Most  States  levied  the  tax  at  the  rate  of  2.7  percent 
in  1938,  with  a  few  higher  rates.     In  previous  years  there  is  more 


OONOENTRATrON  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEfR  Igg 

likelihood  that  the  State  tax  was  higher  than  the  minimum  assumed. 
As  a  result,  a  larger  wage  bill  would  occasionally  be  calculated  than 
was  actually  paid.  On  the  other  hand,  because  Social  Security 
taxes  are  paid  only  on  wages  and  salaries  under  $3,000,  a  wage  bill 
computed  from  the  tax  paid  would  have  a  tendency  to  be  too  smalh 

When  the  1936  and  1937  wage-sales  ratios  were  calculated,  there 
was  in  m.ost  cases  very  little  variation  between  the  2  years.  All 
returns  which  indicated  a  year-to-year  variation  in.  wage  rates  of  more 
than  10  percent  were  subjected  to  further  scrutin3^  The  fiscal  year 
for  these  companies  was  obtained  from  Moody's  1939  Industrial 
Manual  as  also  the  1938  sales  figures  if  they  were  available.  If  the 
fiscal  year  was  the  same  as  the  calendar  year,  the  wage-sales  ratio  was 
calculated  for  1938.  Then  if  the  ratio  exliibited  a  trend  up  or  down, 
the  calculated  wages  were  allowed  to  stand,  provided  the  trend  was 
within  reason.  Som.e  did  not  seem  to  be,  and  the  wages  were  not 
entered. 

Where  the  fiscal  year  ended  in  some  other  month  than  the  calendar 
year,  wages  had  to  be  calculated  by  using  the  number  of  months  of 
each  calendar  year  in  the  fiscal  year  times  the  rate  of  the  tax  levy  in 
the  appropriate  calendar  year.  For  exam.ple,  with  a  fiscal  year 
ending  June  30,  1937,  the  Social  Security  tax  paid  in  the  fiscal  year 
was  divided  by  24  (6  months  at  1  percent  and  6  months  at  3  percent) 
and  the  quotient  multiplied  by  1,200  (12  months  by  100)  to  get  wages 
for  the  1936  fiscal  year.  This  is  a  form  of  extrapolation.  For  1937 
the  wages  were  gotten  by  dividing  the  tax  paid  in  the  1937-38  fiscal 
year  by  42  and  multiplying  the  quotient  by  1,200.  The  1937  wages 
were  obtained  from.  1937-38  fiscal  year  figures  rather  than  from  1936- 
37  fiscal  year  returns,  because  most  returns  had  m.ore  m.onths  in  the 
1937-38  year  than  in  the  1936-37  one. 

One  check  of  the  accuracy  of  tliis  m.ethod  was  a  comparison  of  the 
wage-sales  ratio  for  the  2  years.  In  most  cases  the  ratio  did  not  vary 
much,  although  som.ewhat  more  than  in  the  case  where  the  fiscal  year 
and  calendar  year  were  the  same.  One  error  in  the  method  arises 
from_  the  cyclical  variation  present.  The  calculation  used  assurned 
that  there  was  none.  It  is  apparent,  however,  that  in  the  computation 
of  1936  wages  from  social  security  taxes  paid  in  1936-37,  some  account 
should  be  taken  of  the  fact  that  most  businesses  operated  at  a  higher 
level  in  the  early  pert  of  1937  than  in  1936.  The  wage  bill  as  com- 
puted for  1936  was  larger  than  in  actuality.  When  using  the  1937-38 
fiscal  year  to  get  1937  wages,  just  the  opposite  would  be  true.  Some 
correction  could  have  been  made,  at  great  labor  expense.  W^ages  for 
1937  m.ight  have  been  calculated  from  the  1937-38  fiscal  year  tax 
payments,  and  also  from  the  1936-37  payments.  This  would  have 
given  in  most  cases  a  lower  figure  for  the  first  computation  than  for 
the  second,  because  of  the  depression  in  the  latter  part  of  1937  and  in 
1938.  Then  the  figure  could  have  been  averaged  on  the  basis  of  a 
double  system  of  weighting.  The  number  of  m.onths  of  1937  contained 
in  the  fiscal  years  and  the  rate  of  industrial  activity  for  that  industry 
for  each  month  in  1937  as  given  by  some  of  the  numerous  indexes 
available  would  have  to  be  taken  into  account. 

No  attem.pt  was  made  to  adjust  for  the  seasonal  variation  in  business 
which  should  be  done  where  the  fiscal  year  w^as  not  evenly  divided 
between  the  2  calendar  years. 


240  OONGENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Gross  margin  is  the  sum  of  gross  profits  as  reported  to  the  Securities 
and  Exchange  Commission,  phis  wages  as  calculated.  This  is  not  the 
same  item  as  'Value  added"  as  definited  by  the  Census  Bureau, 
because  there  have  been  excluded  from  the  cost  of  sales  (which, 
added  to  gross  profits,  give  sales),  not  only  the  wages  charged  to  cost 
of  sales  but  also  the  salaries  under  $3,000  included  in  selling,  general, 
and  administrative  expense.  As  a  result,  ''gross  margin"  may  bo 
larger  than  it  logically  should  be.  By  how  much  is  not  known.  An 
additional  unknown  factor  arises  from  the  possibility  of  different 
accounting  concepts  adopted  b^  individual  firms  when  charging  items 
to  cost  of  sales,  or  selling,  general,  and  administrative  expenses. 

Labor  cost  ratio. — This  ratio  is  that  of  wages,  as  calculated  from 
social  security  taxes  paid,  to  total  sales. 

Profit  7'atio. — This  ratio  was  computed  by  taking  the  net  operating 
result  for  the  period  before  interest,  prior  claims,  and  income  tax, 
and  dividing  this  amount  by  the  total  of  invested  capital  at  the  end 
of  the  period.  Invested  capital  consists  of  (a)  long-term  debt  including 
Treasury  bonds  carried  as  assets;  bonds  held  in  sinking  funds;  bonds 
of  subsidiaries  consolidated  held  by  subsidiaries  consolidated,  and  long- 
term  debt  due  within  1  year  for  wliich  funds  had  already  been  ear- 
marked, and  (b)  net  worth,  i.  e.,  capital  stock  and  surplus  less  deficit 
carried  as  an  asset.  Treasury  stock  carried  as  an  asset,  preferred  stock 
held  in  sinking  fund,  and  discount  on  capital  stock  plus  minority 
interest. 

Equity  ratio. — Tliis  ratio  is  that  of  net  worth  (as  previously  defined) 
to  total  debt  (nicluding  long-term  debt  and  current  liabilities). 


OONOENTRATrON  OF  BOONOMIO  POWER 


141 


QSipuBqojani 

Sn08UBll90SIJ,\[ 

■^ 

,c. 

" 

" 

" 

^ 

CO 

81BS9l0tIAV 

-^ 

S 

c^(N  Tfte^ 

-^  ; 

^ 

sajo^s 
^neunjBdaa 

(MOlOSrH 

'-' 

?5 

i  -"l"^  Ol  r-4 

R 

S8io:)s  m^qo 

C^  t^  to  u-J  O  CO  M 

^ 

« 

eo^  icoiocoM 

JS 

Sni.mjo'BjnuBiu 
sndanBii80sii\r 

O  O  t^  -*1  Tt<  rH 

(M 

CO 

(N.-HO>t^cOTt<COi-i 

^  : 

CO 

^nauidtnba 

UOI^B^.IodsU'BJJ, 

l-HOStOC^-^f-r-Ht^COrJl 

t> 

s 

.-l050(NCOOt^rtfTt<iC.-l 

g 

CC<£)CDCOt^»OT-HM>C(MO; 

1 

o 

1            r^coioi-iiocoocoiooi-i 

1 

snojJ9juojs[ 

■*  Tf  to  Tt<  C^  T-l 

?^ 

1  »C  CO  iO  -^  <N  —( 

rH       1 

c5 

I9a!;s  puTJ  uoai 

fO.-(-*IN  COrH 

^^ 

^ 

i  lO  05  ■<*■  (N  CO  1-1 

'-' 

-^ 

^ 

-po.Td     Smpnna: 

-(  M  t^  00  TJH  (N  rt  CS 

" 

^ 

COCOt^l^TtiCMrHC^ 

-'    ; 

o 

CO 

Jaqqny: 

i-HM-H  M 

^^ 

a> 

1-1  r-l  (M  (M  (M 

-^ 

a> 

joqiBa^ 

rHMTj^ 

oo 

C^^INCO 

t^    1 

mneioj^aj 

(N^  >Or-l 

^rH^ 

?3 

IM 

^ 

"* 

^ 

S[Boitn9qo 

CO  C  OV  00  .-<  ^  rH 

.-i(N 

CO 

(NNt^cOt^i-KNi-H 

^^ 

^ 

gni;mjd: 

tHCCCO 

(NO^ 

TT 

.-l(MO(M 

(MC^ 

JO     1 

jadBj 

—1  r^   M  CO  CO  1-1 

w 

irHrH   (N  CO  CO 

si 

1 

jequinq; 

^(M 

CO 

(M 

1 

S9II?X9J, 

rH  lOOOrHCOIN 

^ 

CO  t^  to  Oi  rH  CO  (M 

CO 

oooBqox 

.-H  Tj<  lO  <N  1-1 

^ 

^ 

-^-^i-li-H 

^  \ 

^11 

"1 

sa2Ba8A9a: 

^ 

foc^^co 

C-1 

'^ 

a> 

lo  rM  e^  cq  cq  IN 

(M 

CO      c 

11 

poo^ 

CO.-<-^?OeO<MrHC^rH 

-1 

s 

coo5o>'«^<^^'=^^^   ; 

'^ 

I«*ox 

2S|gg§^S2^S 

i 

^ggssss?^^^^ 

IN 

SI 

»- 

IT 

1- 

i 

c 
c 

i 

J 

c 

c 

c 

c 
I-' 

c 

i 

c 
c 

i 

J 

c 
c 

C 

1 

J 
^  c 

'3 
o 

2.  By  profit  rate  classes  (pay-roll 
and  property  taxes) : 
Deficit 

-1- 

c 
c 

= 

C 
C 

i 

c 

c 

t 

i 

c 

C^ 

c 

1= 

c 

i 

■1- 

c 
c 

ir 
c^ 

J 

c 
> 

c 

1 

i 

o 

142 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


esipnBqojaur 
sno9n'Biiaosip\[ 

^  1 

1 
1 

" 

e^co 

t^ 

^ 

t^ 

aiBsaioqAV 

COCMTf^r-l 

- 

-,,--      ; 

'-' 

CO 

1 

CO 

S8J05S 

t-- -^  00 -#  i-"-l       1 

s 

COCOCi 

^ 

03  Ti<  0  i-i(M 

^ 

S9J0?s  uiBqo 

CO  t-"*<  CO  (N  <-H       1 

^ 

^cor^co 

^ 

CO  CO  t^  CO  10  i-H 

SniJTHOBjnuBca 
sno'anBii30sij\[ 

lO  00  to  03  ■>#  W  CO 

t^il            i-HOOCOINlOr-l 
CO                               r-^r-. 

CO 

Ml 

OOOJt-COCO      \ 

CO 

uoi:jB?Jodsnt3Jj, 

co2c^;o-.o^ 

s 

s^??s^ 

8 

S^JSSg^^-" 

1 

vCjauTqoBjAj; 

Ci  00  CO  00  00 

'- 

§              ^SJ^^^C^S 

2 

'^^c?;^^'-''" 

s 

snojJ9jno|<[ 

<N  lO  CO  -^  r-f  CO  r-4 

0,          ^ot. 

■*    1 

1 

.-^  CO  •>*<  CO  10  r-l 

?5 

t99JS  puB  IIOJJ 

COCOOJ^fO 

^ 

CO 
(N 

<N  Ort  lO     \ 

'^ 

rt  CD  T(<  t^ 'Tf*  CO 

85 

spn 
-pojd     Snipiino: 

CO  "O  00  '^  (N  (M  -^ 

-1 

1 

C^COCO»Ort< 

CO 

CI  w  t>  cr;  (N    1 

?s 

j9qqnH 

COi-Ht-HrH 

05 

10>Ct-4        1 

(N-*  IM<N.-<      i 

1-H 

J9q}B9T: 

(NCO 

■-IC^      1 

00 

.-ioO'--i 

0 

t-H-^tH 

Tfl    1 

0 

1 

ran9ioa!j93 

CO  CO  t^  r-H  C^ 

CO 

i^ 

»CH^TJ< 

^ 

lOrHCOOiOO 

j. 

sieoiragqo 

CO  CO  00  00  CO  Ci  (N 

^ 

iCt-cOCO 

5 

r-l  CJ  l>  t--  <M  (N 

5 

gni^mjj 

rH  TJ<  CO  <N  C-)  r-(  .-1 

;2; 

l^COCNrH 

eg 

1               (M  10  Tt<  ■*  i-l      1 

1        i 

CO 

j9dB<i 

l>-*COCO 

COrH 

i 

(N-MMCO 

1 

tH  COCOOCM      i 

1                  i 

c^ 

jgqrani 

(M 

^ 

CO 

-H^        1 

CI 

i 

! 

^rH 

(N 

S91HX9J, 

(N  '^  CO  "O  CO  »-l  CO 

1 

W  05  ^  10  'it 

5? 

1           (N  oc  CO  r^  .-H    I 

5? 

oooBqoj, 

^^^^ 

COr*< 

■* 

1            COWS'*  rH 

CO 

rH  C»  >-<  CO  IM  i-l 

1 

CO 

S9SBJ9A8a 

CO  «5  CO  ro  rH 

00 

1 

^ 

j                CO  -^  (M  .-.  -5<      1 

^ 

pooj 

O  CO  CO  --I  >C  CO  CO 

10 

^^COCO^      1 

s 

i 

s 

mox 

§gl§^^J§ 

i 

£5|gSS^    1 

5|§SS?5 

1 

o 

11 

>> 
pq 

00 

V 

c 
•<* 

c 
oc 

c; 

c 

3   C 

ci 

'5 

56 

1 

i 

ll 

cSp 

>> 

5i 

c 
c^ 

c 

c 
c 

'5 

c 

5  ri 

i 

0 

1 

1 

0 

m 

10 

c 
■1- 

c 
c 

c 
c 
5 

>4^ 
c 

1 

.0 

1 

OONGENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  143 

Exhibit  1 

Dun  &  Bradstreet,  Inc., 

The  Mercantile  Agency, 

Dear  Sir:  Taxes  are  a  vitally  important  business  problem,  yet  no  one  actually 
knows  the  present  tax  burden  on  trade  or  industry.  This  year's  Dun  &  Brad- 
street  Survey,  while  continuing  the  main  purpose  of  estimating  sales  and  inven- 
tory trends,  asks  you  a  series  of  questions  on  the  amount  of  taxes  your  business 
has  paid. 

The  questions  have  been  prepared  with  great  care,  to  yield  a  maximum  of 
information  with  minimum  effort  on  your  part.  The  findings  will  show  what 
part  business  pays  of  the  total  tax  bill — Federal,  State,  and  local.  This  is  the 
first  attempt  on  so  wide  a  scale  to  obtain  information  of  this  nature,  and  it  may 
have  very  significant  results. 

The  tabulations  will  be  made  by  our  research  and  statistical  division,  and  the 
information  received  on  the  questionnaire  will  not  be  available  to  our  regular 
reporting  divisions.  No  individual  figures  will  be  published;  the  results  will  be 
presented  in  totals  and  averages. 

We  shall  send,  without  charge,  a  complete  summary  of  the  results  to  everyone 
who  participates  by  supplying  us  with  the  raw  material.  These  survey  findings 
will  be  extremely  valuable  and  convincing,  as  they  will  represent  the  experience 
of  thousands  of  businessmen. 

The  questionnaire  has  been  prepared  in  tvv'o  parts,  which  can  be  separated. 
If  there  may  be  a  delay  in  answering  the  tax  burden  questions,  tear  off  the  right- 
hand  sheet  for  later  mailing.  The  value  of  sales  and  inventory  information 
depends  upon  the  speed  with  which  the  results  are  available,  so  kindly  send  in 
at  least  the  business  trend  schedule  as  quickly  as  possible. 
Very  truly  yours, 

A.  D.  Whiteside,  President. 

For  Research  Purposes  Only 

Business  Trend  Survey 

First :  Kindly  return  this  left  half  of  sheet  at  the  earliest  possible  date.  Figures 
from  your  income-tax  return  are  not  necessary. 

Second:  If  tax  figures  are  not  yet  available  at  the  same  time,  detach  right- 
hand  sheet  and  mail  later. 

1.  Type  of  business: 

'Describe  type  of  operation  and  main  line  of  products  handled  or  service 
rendered.  (Examples:  grocery  and  meat  retailing,  radio  manufacturing, 
coal  mining,  plumbing  contractor,  hotel). 


1937  1938 

2.  Annual  sales  (or  volume  of  business) $ $ 

3.  Inventory  (at  end  of  year) $ § 

(Do  not  include  plant  or  equipment  valuation.     Give  fiscal  year  closing 
date  if  not  December  31 ) 

(Give  figures  in  dollars — omit  cents) 

Address  for  Mailing  Residts  of  Survey 

Name  of  concern  (print  or  typewrite) 


(If  a  subsidiary,  please  write  name  of  parent  company 
at  bottom  of  page.) 


Attention  of:   (Department  or  individual). 

Street  address  (print  or  typewrite) 

City  and  State  (print  or  typewrite) 


Mail  this  sheet  direct  to  Dun  &  Bradstreet,  Inc.,  Research  and  Statis- 
tical Division,  290  Broadway,  New  York  City,  or  in  the  Enclosed  Enve- 
lope TO  Our  Local  Office. 


244  OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

For  Research  Purposes  Only 
Tax  Burden  Survey 

The  following  taxes  were  paid  during  1938  by  this  concern: 

(Enter  amount  actually  paid  even  though  you  keep  books  on  accrual  basis. 
The  desired  figures  will,  in  most  cases,  be  m.ore  readily  available  from  tax  schedules 
than  from  the  expense  ledgers.) 

(Make  entry  on  every  line — -"none,"  "no  record,"  or  dollar  amount — omit  cents) 

1.  Federal  taxes  on  business  incom.e: 

(tt)   Corporations:  Include    incom.e,    undistributed    profits, 

corporation  capital  stock,  and  excess-profits  taxes $ 

(6)  Partnerships  and  proprietors:   If  there  is  other  income 

divide  total  tax  proportionately  and  enter  only  total           or 
individual  taxes  paid  on  business  incom.e $ 

2.  Social  security   taxes   and   contributions,   com.bined   State   and 

Federal,  both  old-age  and  unemploym.ent: 

(a)   Employer's  contribution $ 

(6)   Employee's  contribution $ 

3.  Sales  and  excise  taxes  on  outgoing  goods — paid  by  you  direct  to 

a  Governm.ent  body: 

(a)  Federal     (m.anufacturer's     excise     taxes     on     gasoline, 

cigarettes,  liquor,  etc.) - $ 

ih)   State  and  local  (retail  sales  taxes,  tobacco,  liquor  taxes, 

etc.) $ 

4.  All  other  State  and  local  taxes: 

{a)   State  incom.e  taxes — see  instructions  for  item.  1  above--  $ 

(6)   Property    taxes,    on    business    property    only— exclude 

special  assessments $ 

Please  indicate  whether  business  quarters  are:  Owned  D  rented  D 

(c)  Business  franchises,  chain-store  taxes,  etc $ 

{d)   All  other  taxes  and  licenses $ 

5.  If  you  have  m.ade  any  special  study  or  tabulation  of  your  taxes,  particularly 

com.parisons  of  several  years,  we  shall  be  grateful  for  a  copy. 

//  this  tax-survey  sheet  is  returned  separately,  place  name  and  address  in  the  space 
provided  below. 

THE  TAX-BURDEN  SURVEY 

It  is  well  known  that  the  tax  burden  on  business  has  grown  heavier  in  recent 
years,  that  taxes  frequently  absorb  a  large  part  of  potential  profits.  Total  tax 
receipts  of  the  country  can  be  added  up  from.  Federal,  State,  and  local  budgets, 
but  the  tax  burden  on  business  is  not  known  separately.  Do  taxes  bear  most 
heavily  on  sm.all  enterprises,  the  medium  sizes,  or  the  large  ones?  Which  indus- 
tries carry  the  heaviest  burden?  How  much  is  Federal,  how  much  State  and 
local? 

Business  can  tell  its  story  with  more  force,  and  seek  relief  from  inequities  with 
more  chance  of  success,  if  it  has  the  facts. 

Kindly  return  this  sheet  before  April  1,  1939,  to  your  local  Dun  &  Bradstreet 
Office,  or  Direct  to  Research  and  Statistical  Division,  290  Broadway, 
New  York  City. 

Address  for  Mailing  Results  of  Survey 

Fill  in  only  if  this  page  is  returned  separately 

Name  of  concern  (Print  or  typewrite) 

(If  a  subsidiary,  please  write  name  of  parent  company  at  bottom  of  page.) 

Attention  of:    (Departm.ent  or  individual) 

Street  address  (Print  or  typewrite) 

City  and  State  (Print  or  typewrite) 

Exhibit  2 

Department  op  Commerce, 
Office  of  the  Assistant  Secretary, 

Washington. 
The  tax  payments  of  business  enterprise  are  now  being  studied  by  the  Depart- 
ment of  Commerce  in  connection  with  its  work  for  the  Temporary  National 
Economic  Committee. 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


145 


Total  tax  receipts  can  be,  and  have  been,  estimated  by  adding  the  Federal, 
State,  and  local  budgets.  But  such  figures  are  not  enough  to  answer  many  of  the 
tax  questions  of  business.  Are  some  industries  subject  to  heavier  tax  burdens 
than  others?  What  different  types  of  taxes  does  American  business  pay?  In 
what  ways  has  the  business  tax  burden  been  increasing?  In  short,  what  are 
the  fundamental  facts  about  business  taxation  today? 

You  have  already  filed  detailed  statements  about  the  corporation's  business 
with  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission.  But  we  would  like  more  details 
about  your  taxes  over  the  last  few  years  than  the  filed  profits-and-loss  statement 
provides.  The  Department  is,  of  course,  familiar  with  the  general  findings 
of  the  recent  tax  survey  conducted  by  Dun  &  Bradstreet,  Inc.,  for  1938,  but  that 
survey  was  based  on  returns  principally  from  small  and  medium-sized  business. 
Again  we  would  like  more  information. 

You  can  help  us  to  get  these  details  b}^  filling  out  the  attached  one-page 
schedule  and  mailing  it,  before  October  1,  1939,  to  the  Department  of  Com- 
merce. A  franked  addressed  envelope  is  enclosed  for  this  purpose.  Please  note 
that  the  schedule  is  to  be  sent  to  the  Department  of  Commerce,  and  not  to  the 
Securities  and  Exchange  Commission,  and  its  filing  is  of  course  not  subject  to  the 
requirements  of  the  Securities  Exchange  Act  of  1934.  Your  cooperation  and 
that  of  other  business  concerns  is  necessary  if  we  are  to  get  at  the  facts  of  business 
taxation. 

Sincerely  yours, 

WiLLARD  L.  Thorp, 
Director  of  Economic  Studies. 


Department  of  Commerce 
bureau  of  foreign  and  domestic  commerce 
^  Washington,  D.  C. 

Business  taxation  schedule  for  years  1934-38 
Name  of  corporation 


Please  enter  the  following  information  (in  dollars,  omitting  cents)  as  fully  as  your  records  will  permit  and 
according  to  the  same  reporting  base  as  to  subsidiaries  that  was  used  in  Form  10-K  of  your  aimual  report 
to  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission.  Where  exact  figures  are  not  available  and  estimates  have 
been  prepared,  please  identify  the  estimates  by  encircling  the  figures.  Include  only  taxes  paid  direct  to  a 
Government  body.  Do  not  include  taxes  paid  in  connection  with  the  purchase  of  commodities,  such  as 
customs  and  import  duties,  gasoline  taxes,  etc. 


1934 

1935 

1936 

1937 

1938 

1.  Federal  corporation  income  taxes,  including  ex- 

$ 

XXX 

XXX 

$ 

$--- 

$ 

/l    Fpdprfll  panital  stnck  tax 

5.  Federal-State  pay-roll  taxes,  including   old-age 

and  unemployment  taxes 

6.  State  taxes  on  net  income  include  "franchise" 

taxes  in   Cahfomia,    Connecticut,   Montana, 
New  York,  and   Utah  where  ba.sed  on  net 

inpnmp 

XXX 

XXX 

7     Staf-p  calpQ    arns!<;  rpppint<;    crrn<;<?  inrnniR  taYP<? 

8.  Property   taxes,  including  real  estate  and  per- 

9.  Corporation  franchise  and  privilege  taxes  other 

than  nri  inrnmp 

in     Ol-hpr  Ccnppifv^ 



Note.— The  report  on  "total  taxes"  should  agree  with  the  sum  of  your  taxes  classed  as  (1)  operating 
expenses  and  (2)  charges  on  net  income  in  your  annual  report  on  Form  10-K  to  the  Securities  and  Exchange 
Commission.    If  not,  please  explain. 


APPENDIX  F 
TECHNICAL  TABLES 

Table   1. —  United  States  tax  collections,  1860-1938 

[All  figures  in  millions  of  dollars] 

IN  CURRENT  DOLLARS 


Federal  i 

State 

and 

local » 

Total 

Per  capita 

Federal 

State 
and 
local 

Total 

I860                             ....-- 

53 

379 

311 

372 

526 

624 

663 

626 

5,  728 

3,570 

3,137 

3,364 

3,626 

2,808 

1,889 

1,855 

2,954 

3,621 

3,900 

5,084 

6,034 

3  94 
3  281 
3  314 
471 
861 
1,459 
1,597 
1,900 
3,265 
4,016 
4,919 
6,105 
6,798 
6,583 
6,679 
5,675 
5, 855 
6.102 
6,  639 
7,022 
8,777 

147 
660 
625 
843 
1,387 
2,083 
2,260 
2,526 
8,993 
7,586 
8,056 
9,469 
10,  424 
9,391 
8,568 
7,530 
8,809 
9,723 
10.539 
12,  106 
14,811 

1.69 

9.80 

6.18 

5.90 

6.63 

6.77 

6.87 

6.30 

53.77 

32.49 

27.31 

28.07 

29.45 

22.62 

15.12 

14.75 

23.33 

28.39 

30.36 

39.33 

46.48 

2.98 
7.27 
6.25 
7.47 
10.  85 
15.81 
16.55 
19.13 
30.64 
36.  55 
42.82 
50.93 
55.24 
53.04 
53.44 
45.12 
46.24 
47.86 
51.70 
54.33 
67  61 

4.67 

1870                                                                --  - 

17.07 

1880                                       --       ---     -     --  -- 

12.43 

1890 

13.37 

1902                                            --            -  -       - 

17.48 

1910                   

22.58 

1913                                                       -  --     --- 

23.42 

1915                                       --     --  --     -  ---   - 

25.43 

1920                                                           -   -- 

84.41 

1922                                        -.  -   -  - 

69.04 

1925                                                                  -   - 

70.13 

1928                                          -   - 

79.00 

1930                        

84.69 

1931                                           

75.66 

1932                    -       

68.56 

1933                                          

59.87 

1934                      '- 

69.57 

1935                                            . 

76.25 

1936                        

82.06 

1937                                                   ... 

93.66 

1938                    

114.  09 

ADJUSTED  TO  1926  DOLLARS  (BUREAU  OF  LABOR  STATISTICS  WHOLESALE  INDEX) 

Federal 

State 
and 
local 

Total 

Per  capita 

Federal 

State 
and 
local 

Total 

I860                                          

87 

437 

478 

662 

893 

886 

950 

901 

3,710 

3,692 

3,031 

3,479 

4,197 

3,847 

2,915 

2,815 

3,944 

4,526 

4,826 

5,891 

7,677 

154 
324 
482 
838 
1,462 
2,073 
2,288 
2,734 
2,115 
4,153 
4,753 
6,313 
7,868 
9,017 
10,  307 
8,  612 
7,817 
7,628 
8,217 
8,137 
12,  404 

241 
761 
960 
1,  500 
2,355 
2,959 
3,238 
3.635 
5,825 
7,845 
7,784 
9,792 
12,  065 

12.  864 

13,  222 
11,427 
11,761 

12,  154 

13,  043 

14,  028 
20,  081 

2.78 
11.30 
9.49 
10.50 
11.  26 
9.62 
9.84 
9.06 
34.83 
33.60 
26.39 
29.03 
34.09 
30.99 
23.33 
22.38 
31.15 
35.49 
37.  57 
45.58 
58.96 

4.89 
8.39 
9.60 
13.29 
18.42 
22.  45 
23.71 
27.  52 
19.84 
37.80 
41.37 
52.67 
63.93 
72.65 
82.47 
68.47 
61.73 
59.82 
63.99 
62.  95 
95.25 

7.67 

1870                    -     

19.68 

1880                                                     ---  - 

19.09 

1890                     -      

23.  79 

1902                                                   -  

29.68 

1910                          

32.07 

1913                                                 

33.55 

1915                       

36.58 

1920                                                       

58.25 

1922                      

71.40 

1925                                                       

67.76 

1928             

81.70 

1930                                                 

98.02 

1931    

103.64 

1932                                                

105.  80 

1933     

90.85 

1934                                              

92.  88 

1935 

95.31 

1936                                     

101.  56 

1937                                                              

108.  53 

1938      -                       -     

154.  21 

1  Annual  Report  of  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury,  1938,  pp.  410-413,  on  basis  of  warrants  issued  up  to  1915 
and  on  basis  of  dailv  Trasury  statements  (unrevised)  from  1916  onward. 

2  For  years  1860-1930,  inclusive,  Recent  Social  Trends,  p.  1342.  For  1932,  Financial  Statistics  of  State 
and  Local  Governments,  p.  7.  For  1931,  Cost  of  Government  in  the  United  States,  1935-37,  p.  30.  J^or 
1933,  1934,  and  19?.5,  Facing  the  Tax  Problem,  pp.  576-577.  For  1936  and  1937,  Clarence  Heer,  Federal  Aid 
and  the  Tax  Problem,  p.  31.  For  1938,  Bulletin  of  the  Treasury  Department,  August,  1939,  p.  4.  These 
figures  for  State  and  local  taxes  are  obviously  not  comparable  in  any  strict  sense,  because  of  the  divergent 
sources  employed,  but  they  are  believed  valid  for  a  broad  comparison. 

3  Includes  ad  valorem  levies  only. 

146 


OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table   1. —  United  States  tax  collections,  1860-1938 — Continued 

[All  figures  in  millions  of  dollars] 

ADJUSTED  TO  1913  DOLLARS  (NEW  YORK  RESERVE  BOARD  INDEX) 


147 


Federal 

State 
and 
local 

Total 

Per  capita 

Federal 

State 
and 
local 

Total 

1860 

75 

372 

379 

477 

626 

643 

663 

608 

2;  968 

2,250 

1,845 

1,911 

2,158 

1,872 

1,  431 

1,438 

2, 156 

2,497 

2,532 

3,158 

3,918 

132 
275 
383 
604 
1,025 
1,504 
1,597 
1,845 
1,692 
2,542 
2,894 
3,469 
4,046 
4,389 
5,060 
4,399 
4,274 
4,208 
4,311 
4,361 
6,331 

207 
647 
762 
1,081 
1,651 
2,147 
2,260 
2,453 
4,660 
4,801 
4,739 
5.380 
6,204 
6,261 
6,491 
5,837 
6,430 
6,705 
6,943 
7,519 
10,  249 

2.38 
9.61 

7.54 
7.56 
7.89 
6.98 
6.87 
6.12 
27.86 
20.56 
16.06 
15.95 
17.53 
15.08 
11.45 
11.43 
17.03 
19.58 
19.71 
24.43 
30.09 

4.20 
7.13 

7.62 
9.58 
12.92 
16.30 
16.55 
18.57 
15.88 
23.14 
25.19 
28.94 
32.88 
35.36 
40.49 
34.98 
33.75 
33.01 
33.58 
33.74 
48.62 

6.58 
16.74 
15.16 
17.14 
20.81 
23.28 
23.  42 
24.69 
43.74 
43.70 
47.39 
53.80 
50.41 
50.44 
51.  94 
46.41 
50.78 
52.59 
53.29 
58.17 
78.71 

1870 

1880 

1890 

1902           

1910 

1913 

1915 

1920 

1922    -      .          -       -   -       -  . 

1925 

1928    

1930 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936 

1937 

1938— 

148 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


o 

co"    -T    <N.-rTjrrH 

jg 

i 

i^ 

387 
1,951 
1,248 
4,181 

839 

g 

i 

S| 

328 
447 

846 

5,006 

803 

00- 

o 

2 

585 

509 

835 

5,027 

1,115 

i 

si 

358 

834 

164 

3,321 

1,223 

00- 

CO      J;;^ 

03 

05  05  00  t^'O 
CO  CO         CO(N 

1 

a 

i 

00 

2 

427 
145 
707 

""i,"394" 

1,188 

4,892 

997 

oT 

1 

SI 

pf 

1 

2 

i 

O 

Is 

1^   00O-* 

CO 

2 

s§ 

1     1      co"" 

CO 

o 

CO 

2 

<^s 

|§"g2 

§ 

i 

i 

2,623 
417 
743 
359 

1,406 
293 

"""40i" 

i 

co- 

§g 

387 

1,285 

272 

'"""366" 

co 

i 

f 

IS    ^ 

oq- 

o 

2 

23 

ic  lo     1     !co 

GO 

i 

2§^.   i   is 

COOO       1       ICO 

s 

•*- 

CO 
CT> 

^ 

2§   i   is 

CO  CO       1       ' 

Sales 

Highway 

Property 

Another 

i   1 

i  ! 
1 

(NiC.-H(N-^COQO»C 
03  CO  05  (N'  CO  oi  o  oi 

o 
1 

CO  r^  coos  00 

CO  00  .-J  00 1>; 

o 

s 

co<m' 

COiOCil;;© 

o 

8 

(NCO 

CO  CO  CO  00  <N 
id  Tj;  l^  ir£  o 

o 

1 

fin 

COrHOOt^ 

m5  O  M  O  -^ 

,-1          T^rH 

o 

I 

COt-( 

t- 00  CO  00 1^ 
coco    "cooJ 

o 

4.4 
1.5 
7.2 

""  i4."3' 
12.2 
50.2 
10.2 

o 

1 

COr^ 

1  O  t^  O  rH 

o 

s 

icot^oeo 
'<    ■  (N  id  00 

o 

1 

cot^ 
CO(H 

1      ,-1 1> 

o 

8 

I      1  ,-( t^  O 

1      1  ".ji  (N  05 
1      ■        00 

o 

§ 

^co 

loioicco 
!  id    'mo 

1               00  "—I 

o 

i 

^COrH^O^i-^          CO 

o 

1 

Tf  (N  CO      '05 

o^r-IcD    !o6 

CO             1 

o 

t^CO 

■*co    !    !co 

o 

1 

t^CO 

ooo    1    !o5 

o 

1 

OOrt* 

t^co     i     ioo 

ooo    '    !cd 

o 

I 

00    i 

1            i 

^^  i  i-^ 

o 

1 

1 
a 

1 
!  1 

GPL 

3 

o 

2^^ 


■-!  -*J  ^ 


d^!^ 


>cd 

CO 

r^  S  .s  2 


^  c  a  _  w  w 


-,  ^  o  §  o  ^« 
rS  F-.  K  —  .3  w 

g  Qj  o  ^«  a 

'-^  -^  XS  o  -J^  ►t^ 

03  C3  C   03  O  03 

^2,9  S  cm 

°   £    O   g   ry:  ^ 

v.x:^  o  3i  oi 

"g  ^  c3  03  w  O 
fiH  U  ,-^  ^  j::;  ^ 

"  -^  ■"  mz!  " 

tC  C 


I    5^  c«  cc 

•  a,,  w.ti 

oc  C  cj  03 
^  '^  fe  ^- 

2'^  §5 

^'"  S  & 

&al|?^o 
^^'a&al 

^j03    03-55— ^^H 

«f^S.2-9cg 
_o  o3  a 


OONCENTEATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER 


149 


Table  3. — Corporate  gross  and  net  incomes  and  Federal  corporate  income  taxes, 

1909-37 
[In  millions  of  dollars] 


Gross  in- 
come (all 
corpora- 
tions) 


War- 

Net  in- 

profits 

Undis- 

come (net 

Income 

and 

tributed- 

mcome  cor- 

tax 

excess- 

profits 

porations) 

profits 
tax 

tax 

3,590 

21 

(2) 

(») 

3,761 

34 

(2) 

(') 

3,503 

29 

(») 

(2) 

4,151 

35 

(}) 

(2) 

4,714 

43 

(}) 

(») 

3.940 

39 

(?) 

« 

5,310 

57 

(») 

(2) 

8,  766 

172 

(') 

(«) 

10,  730 

604 

1,639 

(») 

8,362 

653 

2,506 

(2) 

9,411 

744 

1,432 

(2) 

7,903 

637 

989 

(«) 

4,336 

366 

335 

(») 

6,964 

775 

8 

(') 

8,322 

937 

(}) 

(2) 

7,587 

882 

(2) 

(2) 

9,584 

1,170 

n 

(') 

9,673 

1,230 

(«) 

8,982 

1,131 

Q) 

(2) 

10,  618 

1,184 

(') 

(2) 

11,  654 

1,193 

(2) 

(2) 

6,429 

712 

(2) 

(») 

3,683 

399 

(2) 

(2) 

2,153 

286 

(2) 

(2) 

2,986 

416 

7 

(2) 

4,275 

588 

8 

(») 

5,165 

710 

25 

(2) 

9,478 

1,035 

22 

145 

9,  635 

1.057 

43 

176 

Total 
tax 


1910 
1911 
1912 
1913. 
1914 
1915. 
1916. 
1917. 
1918. 
1919. 
1920. 
1921. 
1922. 
1923. 
1924. 
1925. 
1926. 
1927. 
1928. 
1929. 
1930- 
1931. 
1932. 
1933. 
1934. 
1935- 
1936. 
1937. 


0) 

(0 

(0 

0) 

(') 

0) 

(') 

35,  328 

84,693 

86,  465 

99,  919 
118,205 

91,  249 
100,  921 
118,  563 
119,229 
134, 260 
142, 130 
144, 398 
152,  782 
160,  622 
136, 062 
107,  515 

81,  084 

83,642 
100,  831 
113,936 
132, 278 
141,967 


21 

34 

29 

35 

43 

39 

67 

172 

2,142 

3, 169 

2,175 

1,625 

702 

784 

937 

882 

1,170 

1,230 

1,131 

1,184 

1,193 

712 

399 

286 

423 

596 

735 

1,191 

1,276 


1  Unavailable. 

2  No  tax  in  force. 

Source:  Statistics  of  Income. 


Table  4. — Federal  taxes  and  corporate  income  available  for  reinvestment  or 

distribution  to  individuals,  1916-37 

[In  millions  of  dollars] 


Total 

Federal 

taxes 

(1) 

Cash  divi- 
dend paid 

out  to 
individuals 

(2) 

Interest 
paid 

(3) 

Deprecia- 
tion and 
depletion 

(4) 

Corporate 

profits 
(excluding 
intercor- 
porate 
dividends) 
after  Fed- 
eral taxes 

(5) 

Corporate 
income 
available 
for  invest- 
ment ((5) 
less  (2)) 

(6) 

1916. 

172 

2,142 

3,159 

2,175 

1,625 

702 

784 

937 

882 

1,170 

1,230 

1,131 

1,184 

1.193 

712 

399 

286 

423 

596 

735 

1,191 

1.276 

8,766 
10,  730 
3,362 
9,411 
7,903 
4,336 
6,964 
7,721 
7,107 
8,808 
8,842 
8,259 
9,922 
10,  891 
6.067 
3,500 
2.015 
2,717 
3.877 
4.627 
6.031 
6,067 

1917  - 

1918. -.. 

1919 

1920 

1921 

1922 

1923 

2,376 
2,463 
2,752 
2,981 
3,069 
3.396 
3.626 
2,862 
1,499 
863 
889 
1.030 
1,151 
1,706 
1,664 

2,302 
2,379 
2,739 
3,125 
2,792 
3,250 
3,602 
2,867 
1.823 
1.292 
1,627 
1.872 
2,084 
2,674 
2,855 

1924... 

1925 

1926 

4,287 
4,481 
4,990 
5,653 
6,077 
3,019 
1,883 
1,946 
2,912 
3,169 
4,675 
4,794 

4,555 

1927... 

3,778 

1928. 

4,932 

1929 

5,238 

1930 

990 

1931 

481 

1932 

132 

1933 

771 

1934      

965 

1935 

1,468 

1936 

1,356 

1937 

1.263 

Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 
262698— 41— No.  9 11 


150 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  5. — Effect  of  1932  abolition  of  minimum  income  exemption  hy  size  classes  and 

industries 


Federal  tax  as  percent  of 

net  income  (after  prior 

year's  loss) 


Years 


Under    $50- 
$50       $100 


Size  classes  (based  on  assets  in  thousands) 


$100- 
$250 


$250- 
$500 


$500- 
$1,000 


$1, 000- 
$5,000 


$5,  000- 
$10,000 


$10,000- 
$50,000 


Over 
$50,000 


Mining 

Trade 

Service 

Construction. 

Public  utilities 

Finance 

Total  manufacturing 
Food  and  beverages.. 

Tobacco 

Textiles 

Leather 

Rubber 

Forest  products 

Paper 

Printing 

Chemicals 

Stone,  clay,  glass 

Metals 


1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 
1931 
1932 


6.7 
13.4 

2.5 
13.1 

4.0 
13.3 

3.0 
12.9 

3.7 
13.3 

3.0 
13.6 

3.4 
13.5 

4.8 
12.2 

7.2 
13.8 

2.0 
12.8 

3.4 
13.1 

5.0 
14.0 

2.1 
13.0 

3.2 
13.4 

2.9 
13.5 

4.4 
13.5 

1.5 
12.7 

2.9 
13.6 


7.8 
13.7 

5.4 
13.4 

7.2 
13.6 

7.3 
13.5 

7.5 
13.5 

4.2 
13.6 


13.4 

7.2 
13.4 

4.4 
12.8 

6.0 
13.3 

6.6 
13.5 

6.3 
13.0 

6.8 
13.9 

5.9 
13.1 

6.6 
13.5 

6.9 
13.6 

6.6 
13.8 

6.9 
13.0 


13.7 

8.4 
13.5 

9.3 
13.6 

9.9 
13.5 

9.1 
13.6 

6.3 
13.6 

9.5 
13.5 

9.8 
13.4 
10.8 
13.8 

8.8 
13.3 

9.3 
13.5 
12.0 
13.6 

8.8 
13.4 

9.4 
13.9 

9.6 
13.7 
10.2 
13.4 

9.0 
13.7 

9.0 
13.4 


11.2 
13.6 
10.6 
13.5 
11.3 
13.5 
11.4 
13.6 
11.0 
13.6 

8.4 
13.5 
11.2 
13.4 
11.4 
13.2 
11.0 
14.2 
11.0 
13.5 
11.2 
13.0 
11.4 
13.6 

9.9 
13.5 
11.2 
13.5 
11.3 
13.7 
ll.fi 
13.5 
10.8 
13.5 
11.1 
13.6 


11.4 
13.7 
11.5 
13.6 
11.5 
13.7 
11.7 
13.6 
11.7 
13.6 
9.7 
13.7 
11.7 
13.7 
11.7 
13.6 
11.8 
13.9 
11.5 
13.6 
12.0 
13.0 
11.5 
18.2 
12.0 
13.7 
11.7 
15.0 
11.8 
13.7 
11.8 
12.5 
11.5 
13.5 
11.7 
13.6 


11.6 
13.8 
12.0 
13.5 
12.0 
14.2 
12.0 
13.8 
12.0 
13.7 
11.4 
13.5 
12.0 
13.7 
12.0 
13.7 
11.6 
13.8 
12.0 
13.5 
11.9 
13.6 
12.0 
115 
11.9 
13.7 
12.0 
13.7 
11.8 
13.8 
12.0 
13.6 
11.7 
13.7 
12.0 
13.7 


12.0 
13.8 
11.9 
13.9 
12.0 
13.9 
12.0 
13.7 
12.0 
13.8 
11.9 
13.7 
12.0 
13.7 
12.0 
13.7 
12.1 
13.8 
12.0 
12.8 
12.0 
13.8 
12.0 
14.4 
11.8 
13.9 
12.0 
13.5 
12.0 
13.8 
12.0 
13.8 
12.0 
13.8 
12.0 
13.6 


12.0 
13.9 
11.7 
13.9 
12.0 
13.7 
12.0 
13.8 
12.0 
13.8 
12.0 
13.8 
12.0 
13.8 
12.0 
13.9 
12.0 
14.0 
12.0 
12.7 
12.0 
12.5 


12.0 
14.5 
12.0 
14.1 
12.0 
13.6 
12.0 


12.0 
14.1 
12.0 
13.8 
12.0 
13.9 
12.0 
13.9 
12.0 
13.7 
12.0 
13.0 
12.0 
13.6 
12.0 
14.1 


12.2 


12.0 
13.7 
12.0 
14.0 
12.0 
14.0 
12.0 
13.8 
12.0 
14.1 


12.0 
13.8 
12.0 
13.9 
12.1 
14.3 
12.0 
13.9 
12.0 
14.0 


Source:  Computed  from  the  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue. 
Table  6. — Statutory  deductions  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts  hy  size  classes,  1937 


Size  classes  (assets 
in  thousands) 

Cost  of 
goods 
and  op- 
eration 

Com- 
pensa- 
tion of 
officers 

Rent 
paid 

Bad 
debts 

Interest 
paid 

Taxes 
paid 

Depre- 
ciation 

Deple- 
tion 

Other  I 
deduc- 
tions 

Total 
deduc- 
tions 

Under  $50 

73.2 
75.2 
74.4 
72.6 
71.5 
68.5 
65.9 
63.6 
64.0 
62.2 

6.3 

4.4 

3.6 

2.9 

2.4 

1.6 

1.1 

.7 

.5 

.3 

2.8 

1.6 

1.3 

1.1 

1.0 

.9 

.9 

.9 

.7 

.8 

0.6 
.6 
.6 
.6 
.6 
.6 
.6 
.5 
.4 
.4 

0.5 
.8 
1.0 
1.3 
1.4 

2.2 
3.0 
4.0 

1.2 
1.4 
1.6 
2.0 
2.3 
2.6 
2.8 
2.8 
3.6 
3.5 

1.2 
1.4 
1.5 
1.7 
1.9 
2.3 
2.6 
2.9 
2.9 
3.1 

0) 
0.1 

.1 

.2 

\l 
.5 
.6 

.8 
.6 

15.2 
14.1 
14.3 
15.0 
15.3 
16.3 
17.0 
17.2 
16.0 
14.6 

101.2 

$50  to  $100 

99.5 

$100  to  $250 

98.6 

$250  to  $500 

97.5 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

.$5,000  to  $10.000.... 
$10,000  to  $50,000. . . 
$50,000  to  $100,000.. 
Over  $100,000 

96.8 
94.9 
93.6 
91.6 
91.9 
89.4 

Total 

67.8 

2.0 

1.1             .5 

2.1 

2.6 

2.3 

.4 

15.5 

94.4 

» Includes  contributions  and  capital  losses. 
Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


151 


Table  7. — Statutory   deductions   as   percent   of  total  corporate  receipts,  1936,    hy 
size  of  corporations  and  industries 

[All  corporation  Income-tax  returns  subject  to  the  1936  Revenue  Actl 
PART  I.  MAJOR  INDUSTRIES 


Si7e  classes  based  on  total 
assets  (in  thousands) 


Manufac- 
turing (in- 
cluding 
miscel- 
laneous 
manufac- 
turing) 1 


Mining 

Trade 

Service 

Construc- 
tion 

Public 

utilities 

Finance 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1.000 

$1,000  to  $5,000-... 
$5,000  to  $10.000. . . 
$10,000  to  ,$50,000.. 
$50,000  to  $100,000. 
Over  $100,000 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

.$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

$5,000  to  $10.000 

$10,000  to  $50,000.... 
$50,000  to  $100,000... 
Over  $100.000 


Under  $50.. 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500.. 

$500  to$j,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000--.. 
$5,000  to  $10,000... 
$10,000  to  $50.000.. 
$50,000  to  $100,000. 
Over  $100,000 


Cost  of  goods  sold  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

.$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1.000 

$1,000  to  $5,000... 
$5,000  to  $10,000-. 
$50,000  to  $50,000. 
$10,000  to  $100,000 
Over  $100,000 


70.1 
73.9 
74.9 
75.0 
74.0 
72.4 
71.6 

67!  1 
76.2 


29.1 

77.8 

(2) 

44.4 

(2) 

40.2 

79.5 

(2) 

42.3 

i}) 

46.4 

79.2 

(2) 

35.1 

(2) 

62.5 

78.0 

(}) 

23.6 

(2) 

65.1 

77.5 

(2) 

24.3 

(2) 

58.8 

78.1 

(2) 

21.6 

(2) 

56.4 

77.8 

(2) 

28.7 

(2) 

58.6 

74.6 

(2) 

.1 

(?) 

48.4 

69.1 

(2) 

(3) 

(2) 

54.1 

70.6 

i?) 

(?) 

(2) 

Cost  of  operations  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts 


7 

32.3 

2.5 

47.4 

30.8 

54.8 

9 

23.9 

1.7 

40.6 

33.2 

57.4 

2 

17.9 

1.1 

38.4 

41.3 

58.9 

3 

.9 

.3 

29.1 

53.2 

60.9 

3 

.1 

.2 

26.1 

50.6 

59.6 

3 

.6 

.3 

28.8 

48.2 

55.4 

1 

.2 

.3 

25.4 

44.5 

52.0 

1 

.2 

{') 

32.2 

82.7 

45.3 

4 

1.2 

4.0 

52.0 

(3) 

49.9 

4 

.1 

.2 

71.3 

Q) 

52.6 

Compensation  of  officers  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts 


1 

6.9 

4.9 

9.6 

9.0 

7.6 

6 

5.1 

3.4 

7.3 

6.7 

5.6 

3 

4.1 

2.8 

5.6 

5.5 

3.9 

0 

3.2 

2.0 

3.9 

11.0 

2.8 

4 

2.3 

1.6 

3.6 

3.6 

2.0 

5 

1.7 

1.0 

2.1 

2.4 

1.2 

0 

1.1 

.5 

1.0 

1.4 

.8 

7 

.4 

.7 

.7 

.5 

4 

.5 

.4 

.6 

Q) 

.4 

1 

.4 

.1 

(?) 

i?) 

.1 

Rent  paid  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts 


1.9 
1. 1 
.8 
.5 
.4 
.4 
.3 
.4 


,1 

2.2 

7.6 

0.9 

3.6 

,6 

1.3 

5.8 

.6 

2.9 

.7 

1.2 

4.8 

.4 

2.4 

.4 

1.2 

4.1 

.3 

1.9 

.4 

1.2 

3.8 

.3 

2.1 

5 

1.3 

4.0 

.4 

1.2 

.4 

1.2 

3.6 

.2 

1.1 

.4 

2.1 

4.1 

.7 

,7 

.2 

1.3 

6.7 

(3) 

.8 

.1 

2.6 

.8 

(3) 

.9 

56.5 

62.4^ 

41.9 

2.1 

1.5 

.3 

.8 

.9 

.8 

1.5 


11.3 

7.8 
9.1 
11.8 
10.4 
7.0 
3.7 
2.2 
2.2 
2.2 


3.6 
1.7 
2.6 
2.1 
1.5 


1.7 


See  footnote  at  end  of  table. 


152 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  7. — Statutory   deductions   as   percent   of  total  corporate  receipts,  1936,    by 
size  of  corporations  and  industries — Continued 

[All  corporation  income-tax  returns  subject  to  the  1936  Revenue  Act] 


Size  classes  based  on  total 
assets  (in  thousands) 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$600  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000^.. 
$5,000  to  $10,000.. 
$10,000  to  $50,000. 
$50,000  to  $100,000 
Over  $100,000 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250. 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000... 
$5,000  to  $10,000- . 
$10,000  to  $50,000. 
$50,000  to  $100,000 
Over  $100,000 


Under  $50 

$50to$100_ 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500... 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

$5,000  to  $10,000... 
$10,000  to  $50,000.. 
$50,000  to  $100,000. 
Over  $100,000 


Manufac- 
turing (in- 
cluding 
miscel- 
laneous 
manufac- 
turing) 


■  Mining 

Trade 

Service 

Construc- 
tion 

Public 
utilities 

Finance 


0.7 
.9 
1.2 
1.5 
2.1 
2.1 
2.2 
2.6 
2.3 
1.4 


Under  $50 

$50  to  .$100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000... 
$5,000  to  $10,000.. 
$10,000  to  $50,000. 
$50,000  to  $100,000 
Over  $100,000 


Bad  debts  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts 


0.6 

0.7 

0.5 

.5 

.6 

.6 

.5 

.7 

.7 

.5 

.4 

.6 

.6 

.7 

.4 

.4 

.6 

.4 

.3 

o 

.3 

.4 

.5 

.3 

.2 

.2 

.3 

.2 

.3 

.1 

0.6 
.8 
.7 
.7 

1.0 

1.1 
.8 

1.9 
.3 

3.0 


0.5 

0.7 

.4 

.6 

.4 

.5 

.3 

.5 

.6 

,4 

.7 

.4 

.1 

.2 

.1 

.2 

) 

.2 

Interest  paid  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts 


0.4 

1.2 

0.3 

0.7 

0.3 

0.9 

.5 

1.2 

.4 

2.2 

1.0 

.6 

1.5 

.4 

4.1 

1.6 

.6 

1.6 

.4 

7.5 

3.0 

.6 

2.2 

.4 

8.6 

3.7 

.5 

2.2 

.5 

8.2 

7.0 

.6 

3.0 

.3 

14.6 

.6 

8.8 

.7 

2.2 

.5 

9.3 

.9 

10.3 

.9 

3.5 

.3 

8.4 

(3) 

12.9 

.5 

2.9 

.3 

2.7 

(') 

11.9 

Taxes  paid  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts 


0.9 

0.6 

1.5 

0.6 

1.9 

.8 

.6 

2.8 

1.1 

2.5 

1.1 

.6 

4.2 

1.1 

3.1 

1.1 

.7 

6.8 

.8 

3.8 

1.0 

.8 

7.7 

.9 

3.9 

1.0 

.7 

7.3 

1.0 

5.1 

1.1 

.  7 

10.6 

1.3 

5.6 

1.0 

1.1 

6.9 

1.7 

6.8 

4.5 

.9 

4.4 

(3) 

7.4 

8.5 

.9 

.3 

(3) 

7.4 

Depreciation  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts 


1.4 

4.7 

0.6 

2.6 

1.0 

5.0 

1.5 

4.9 

.6 

4.2 

1.6 

5.6 

1.5 

5.1 

.6 

5.2 

1.8 

5.8 

1.7 

5.7 

.5 

7.2 

2.1 

6.4 

1.8 

5.2 

.6 

8.1 

2.8 

6.9 

2.2 

5.9 

.6 

7.6 

3.2 

8.7 

2.4 

5.9 

.7 

10.9 

2.9 

9.8 

2.7 

5.7 

1.0 

7.0 

2.1 

10.8 

2.9 

6.7 

.7 

4.5 

(3) 

9.1 

2.6 

4.2 

.7 

.2 

(') 

6.6 

0.7 
.7 
1.4 
3.6 
3.8 
3.5 
3.0 
2.2 
2.3 
3.7 


1.6 
2.5 
5.5 
12.2 
11.3 
9.0 
8.4 
6.1 
6.2 
12.4 


6.6 
7.4 
10.1 
12.5 
9.9 
7.8 
5.9 
10.6 
3.0 
4.5 


1.2 
1.8 
3.0 
4.7 
4.1 
3.0 
1.9 
1.4 
.9 
1.7 


See  footnotes  at  end  of  table. 


GONOENTRATrON  OF  EOONOMIC  POAVER 


15S 


Table  l.Statutory   deductions   as   percent   of  total  corporate  receipts,  1936,    hy 
size  of  corporations  and  industries — Continued 

[All  corporation  income-tax  returns  subject  to  the  193G  Revenue  Act] 


Size  classes  based  on  total 
assets  (in  thousands) 

Manufac- 
turing (in- 
cluding 
miscel- 
laneous 
manufac- 
turing) 

Mining 

Trade 

Service 

Construc- 
tion 

Public 
utilities 

Finance 

Depletion  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts 

Under  $50    -. 

(') 
(0 
0.1 

.1 

.2 
.2 
.6 

.7 

3.7 
4.0 
4.5 
6.3 
6.4 
7.6 
9.0 
7.2 
11.7 
6.8 

(^) 

(*) 
(*) 

(') 
(*) 
(') 
(*) 
(<) 
(*) 

(*) 
(0 

0.1 
0) 

.1 
{*) 
(') 
(*) 

8 

(*) 

(*) 

(*) 
0.1 
.1 
.1 
.4 
.3 
.2 
.1 

i 

(*) 
(^) 
(<) 
0) 

$50  to  $100     - 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500         

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

(4) 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

(*) 

Over  $100,000 

(<) 

Net  capital  loss  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts 

Under  $50 

0.1 
(*) 

(*) 
(*) 

0.1 
.1 
.3 

1.1 
.4 
.4 
.3 

0 

(0 

8 

0.1 
.1 
.1 

.2 
.2 
.2 

0) 
(') 
(') 

0.6 
.4 
.3 
.1 
.1 
.2 

(3) 

0.7 
.1 
.2 
.1 

(*) 
(*) 
(*) 

0.1 

$50  to  $100    - 

.1 

$100  to  $250 

.2 

$250  to  $500 

.5 

$500  to  $1,000 

1.0 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

.5 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

.3 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

.1 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

.1 

Ovpr  $100,000 

(*) 

other  deductions  as  percent  of  corporate  receipts 

Under  $50      

13.1 
12.7 
12.4 
12.9 
12.9 
13.4 
13.2 
13.6 
14.8 
9.7 

23.0 
18.7 
15.2 
13.6 
13.7 
14.1 
11.7 
12.3 
14.1 
8.6 

10.9 
11.1 
12.1 
13.3 
13.7 
14.3 
14.9 
16.4 
25.0 
17.5 

30.7 
35.5 
35.2 
39.7 
41.3 
40.1 
37.9 
39.2 
15.4 
26.6 

14.7 
12.3 
11.7 
11.3 
10.3 
12.6 
13.6 
4.0 

(3) 

(3) 

27.6 
22.2 
19.1 
14.0 
14.1 
13.5 
11.6 
13.0 
12.1 
11.7 

15.4 

$50  to  $100 

12.9 

$100  to  $250 

18.2 

$250  to  $500 

27.0 

$500  to  $1,000 

31.1 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

32.3 

$5,000  to  $10,000.. 

43.9 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

49.6 

$50,000  to  $100,000 . 

30.7 

Over  $100,000         

28.6 

1  Includes  income-tax  returns  with  fiscal  year  ending  July-November  1936. 

2  All  reported  as  "cost  of  operations." 

3  No  corporation. 

*  Less  than  0.05  percent. 
'  No  deduction  claimed. 

Source;  Computed  from  the  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue. 


154 


GONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


-2-3 


sa 


(X>  3 

II 


cot^-<#o>»oi-iooi-HOt^ 


(Nt»<C^(N»0<NC»COMi 


O  >o  oo  ci  t--^ -^  t>  ( 

CO  ;0  CC  O  CD  CO  *0  < 


C<>QOiOi-icOt^COOiOO(N 

t~-t^r-oooot^cDt^«0!0 


COCOtOCOCOCD'OCO'OiO 


icoooos'oost-.Tfcoco 


MtNt^t^i-i. 


O0Jr-<«Cirt<f000CC05l0 


00  CO  ■*  CO  f-H  t-H  00  CO 
00  •-<■  CO  Tti  CO  ^"  eo  1--^ 

t>.00000000000000' 


t>OSt^O5CO0000t^ 


ioi-iCT>cot^ooo500oo 


00C0<NO>000«Ot^MM 

t^t^t>.t^i>t~-t>Trit^oo 


Ot^COCOt^r-tOl^C 


eq^io.-ico' 


0005l^0000>-it^ 


t>t^t^0000O5COt 


H  t^  CO 
^COOO 


o  05  eo 


00(NOOi-iC^^         rH 

eo^    *    *    *    *,^  *,-~,.^ 

OOOrHi-l 

ecoO'«<.-i      loooi-ic^oo 

O  00  ■*  ■^  t^  Tfl  l-H 

00  O  C^  CO  CO -H  (N 
O»(MOS00C^        C<» 

d    *   '    *   '^^^  "^^^^^ 

Ttl  05  CO  ■<*l  rH  CD  r-l  ■<1<         O 
e4 rHCC         1-5 


e^r-IN  1-1 


rH  ic  eo  ic  CO  "O      eo 
^oirA    '    '    ' 


rHO(N-* 
(NrH-       •       • 


COOS  rH  CO  IM  CO        1-H 
^.      .^      .      .      .  . 


05  lO  CO  •#  oo 

t>:  CD  ■*  CO  C4  rH 


00  COCOrH  05  OJ 
C5  t>:  O  ■><'  C4  rH 


t^CO-^OSrHrH 

cJ  t^«ocoeo  ci 


COOst^cOOJOS 
CD  f-i  C^'  r-i 


»o  t^t-»  000  05 

CJ  CO  '*■  -^  C^  rH 


05  Ttl  Tf  00  o>  o 

o4  oi  t^  ui  eo  oi 


rHeO00  00>Ot>. 
CO  CO  ■*  CO  Ci  rH 


t- ■<*<■«*<  CO  CO  CO 
t^  «d  •*■  CO  <N  rH 


»o  e^  o>  t^QO  ■* 

00  CD  ■<^'  CO  C^  rH 


»O05C0  00OC0 
t>^  ■<*;  CO  IN  Ci  rH 


W  rH  CO  t^  ■*  t^ 

CD  ■*■  CO  C^'  C^'  rH 


N  »0  CT>  t^  C<1  ■* 

00  »d  CO  C4  N  rH 


00  CO  IM  CO  O  i-O 
t>^  i*<  ^'  CO  CO  rn' 


oseorHr^eoe^ 

CO  O  CO  C^  C^'  rH 


C0'<*<t^0'00 
■^  CO  C^'  C<i  r-i  rH 


'    'ooo 

h-*  «^  ««^  «<^  «^  «^  «/?  ^  €«^  O 


ooo 
o  o  _r- 

,_    ,^  ._^         -OlOrHj 

a-  o+j-i-^+joooo  . 
fl  o  o  lo  o  '^'-io  o  > 

€»  €^  6^  «^  €^  ««^  «^  «»  O 


;    i    i    ;dg 

5|rH€l^€^€«^  O 

P  lO  rH  d  lO  rH 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


155 


NC^OOtOCOCOlClOCO 


oot^Tftcoe^(Ncio< 


00t>.»O-<»(CSf0t^(Nrt<CJ 


OC^TjiC^CO-^l^OOt^t^ 


M.-H 1 


N  (N  1-5  1-;  -5  i4      ■  r-J      '  r-i 


fOQO»o-^-^eoeonc^r-i 


»-io005t^eO«^rt<i-(irtiO 


CD  O  00  >0  Tf(  CO  00  f 


OSt-HOt^OOOOt^O 


I  ^  00  Tji  CO  C»  C«  C^  1 


W  r-i 


C<«0>»OiOC^C>^^C<)i 


cot^cOTt<e<ST(<eo>0'^c» 


)  lO  »OUOM<M  (M  rS  »H 


iCOOiOTfliOCOTj<C^C«5 


0500t>-0000>OC^iC 


iO(NCD00iMCOTt<C^i-lN 


it>-oooe^OTt<fOi-<i-i 


ooiooooooocDcoi-Hio 


1  CO  Tt<  "O  e<i  c<no  w  . 


^^ooooooo5l>•oo 

C5      '      '      "rH      *      '      ■ 


OOUSCOt^^COeOrHC^'* 


,j<  T^  CO  «  (N  C>»  S^ 

> C35, 


cc  CO  eo  CO  CO  »o  N 


■^c<5eccoc^i-i^c<»i-i 


ioco»ooooooeocoi 
o 


■^•<*i'^cococ<i.-ie^' 
o 


»ot^t^t^t^»oe<>»o 


«3  O  CO  iO  CD  ■«*<  O  < 


OOCOlOOOCDlCt^OOCOlO 


i0Oi0>O>CiC0t>.t^Tti00 


»OCO00t>-O5t^r-<O>O5b» 

o >-J    ■  1-5  id 


Tj<'il<»CiOC0000500i>0 

O i-I  t^  T}< 


CDOC'OiOOQOC^-«*<CO(N 


Tj*  Tjt  >o  ■*  lo  CO  eo      T-io 

O _    -N 


eo»0'tiioio>OT»<M 


iM  CO  CO  Tt<  eo  CO » 


iOCO««Ol^t^O>'*N 

c5 


ioio«o«D«oc<'<»<N»-<eo 
o '^    ' 


n<iOCOt>.t^CO00'^00 

o , 


eoio>o«oio»oco»ot^c^ 


§8 

t-^  o  o  o*f  *f  oo« 
-O  +^  o  o  o  §  g  ^.==2- ! 


ss 


=  88 


Loog 
.    i <5 g o "o^ ^^=i 
g8c^S^*^^oog 

S  o-ii+^-MOOOo  ^^ 
-O^ooogg^-^-o 

lt^OT-((MlOr-(10— 1>0— . 

I-' ee- ^  ««■ -ae- se- ««■  «/^  ««■  ^ 


oo  _r 

-    go§g§8 

O  O  O  lO  r-l  %^««.0 

ISO     r«/r6e^ r^ 


"O  ■'^  o  o  o      S  ^^  S 
fl  o  o  «o  o  '^   -oo  t> 

t^  «l  fiS- ^  ««•  s?- ««■  ^  «^  o 


156 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


CO 

•1 

2 

a 

1 

'3 
P. 

1 

O^C«Tf<«>OrHOt^Tj< 

i2 
.S* 

1 

o 
o 

a 

o 

1 
1 

<NU5OOO>0rHt^»CO 

^'  ^  ^  Ci  rn"  rA  ciC^rArA 

££SSSSS 

1 

00Oi-lN<NC<5C0«0000 
O  rM  rH  T-i  r-;  ,-;  rH  .-;  rH  >-; 

i>ooo50'-i-*t^oe^co 

i-i  I-;  rH  (N  es  c4  c<i  im'  o  -^^ 

oec-^iO"5t^ooooooc< 

«5  (N  r-l  <N  CO  (N  00  05  00  rH 

,-1        ,-i,-i,-iio 

Neococo'coo-d^-^eo 

££ 

2S 

oooeoooi>oo05«o-*»o 

»OC<JO00f-iOO-<*»CO 

w  c<i  (N  (N  co'  CO  CO  co"  »c  lo 

i-(IN;Ot>.0 

to  Ad     'i-H     •     •ntJh'csi 

££ 

1 

o 

(N  M<  TJH  O  00  O  <N  <©  00  »0 

^co 

,_ii-<i-ii-ir-(e^c^coc<)iM 

£   £££ 

1 
.9 

Ph 

Or-Hl-Hi-HrSi-Hi-Jc^iT-icO 

CO<NrHO<Ni-(005Tf<l> 

.1 

C<i  C4  (N  C^  <M  (N  (N  r-;  r-;  C<« 

■^v-^WWWWW 

1 

«t^O5Oe0-*0000rH-<*< 

tot>.ooojeo»oc<ic^e<3o 

pHrHrMr-5c^CO-<l'-<i'lO-* 

1 

^rH 

C5     •     •  ^' rt"  ,4  ^- ,-i  (M*  <N 

1S§ 

^1 

ciooi-iT»<ioooMiNooeo 

O  ^  r^  r^  -;  ,-;  C4  (M"  (N  M 

Tl<iC<DC»<NO5-*i«O00C^ 

8 

iH  .1  CO  «5  00  ■*  Tti 

^rHrHrtC^deOTjJ^'^O 

o    •    •    •    -c^co 

H 

1 

»^ooa)0»ooi»ccoc<«eo 

T*4  05  oj  .-I  Tj<  t^  c^  t>      eo 

c5              r-;.HtHe<5CO»rf«c5 

r-J  1-5  i-H  cs  c^'  c4  c<i  c>i      w 

C^S^S^S^S^C^  S^ 

1 

iot^ot^ccoooo 

t^Ol^t^OOOSOSt^ 

c5^ -^"^^ 

£££££££ 

1 

•^eoeo-*iot>t^05 

o 

£££££££ 

S 
2 
^ 

U5  O  00  O  rH  CO  T»<  »C  (N 

0'-H-<J<Or-tTt<i-l050 

I-H  r^  rl  r-l  CSJ  (N  eo*  M  rj;  ^ 

c^c^c^c^s^s^s^ 

1 

Mt^00rH»Oe0O00«Oa5 

on>oooooo3oot^-<i< 

O      •       'rn'r^,-;      ■       •       ■ 

(N  CO  od  CO  (N  t>-"  iM'  M  rt'  ^_^ 

WWS^WWWW 

^ 

«>r^0000t^iMCOiO(NC<» 

l:^  00  00  >0 -*  «>0  (N  (N  CO 

O             •               rt  rt  rt  CO  M 

^  ^  ^  ^  pH*  ^  ^'  C^  ^'  ^ 

^ 

s 

ilfli 

Si 

8 

« 

5 

ill 

CONCBNTKATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


157 


r-4C005C0000iCT>t>.Oa> 
»0  u-5  ro  lO  »0  iO  00  CO  OS  o> 

coeo(M-^M050500(No 

•^'  fO  00  05  I©  05  IN  CO  00  «6 

i-ir>.i-i->*ooo«oooi>->o 
^i  00  00 1>  05  o  o  o  rt'  im' 

(M_r-H^r-(Oq(MrH<Nr-l 

ooododooodoooio^' 

r-HrtrHr-fr-((Mrtr-ieOM 

eo<M*c<icoodo«>05t^e<i 

,-|rH,-(r-l,-((Mr-l,-l         CO 

COOOO'*OOOi-IOCO» 
0^rHrHO^CO-<*'oCO 

(Meoco»ca>u50oocoio 

.-lrHi-lrHr-l,-lrHf-l(N<N 

ONt^coococ^o 
c>05o6odoJoJt>^«d 

OO^OOOOOOOCO 

o  o  o  o  -!  (m'  c3  00  ^_,^_^ 

(MOt^-^i-KN'^'l^O 

cJoooododooooi-JoJ^^ 

lO-^oiciN-^oo-^oai 
coooot-^Mt^coodio 

loi-ioioo'^t^cioo 

to  l>^  CO  t^  t^  00  Co'  rj<  00  ^^ 

cot^or^-^oowoorH 

^  ^'  rH  ^'  r-J  •^'  i-I  CC5  lO  OS 


o_o§ 


Sr2.««-««-«^  o  o  -is  is  o 
«  o+-=-w*^oooo  t^ 
fl  o  o  »g  o  '<'r-o  o  t> 
I— '  «^  ««■  €/^  ^  ««•««•««•  se- V 


o  o 


O  O  o  lO  ' 

««^«^«j  o  o  -w  +^  2 

o  o  0"^*^00€«- 
o>oo^   -oo  > 

r-t(NlO.-|lOrHlO/-s 

€i9^  ae- €«■€©■  «^  €^  ^ '^ 


P  0) 

o 

^a 

^ 

S-3 

V, 

i 

^o-y 

^ 

8 

o  S  o 

158 

Table  8, 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

— Deductions  for  prior  years'  losses  as  percent  of  taxable  net  income,  by 
industries. 


[Net  returns  only] 


1922 

1923 

1924 

1925 

1926 

1927 

1928 

1929 

1930 

1931 

1932 

Manufacturing 

9.3 
7.6 
6.8 
12.0 
55.6 
11.7 
10.1 
2.4 
5.8 
3.2 
13.1 
10.6 
9.6 
2.1 
6.3 
1.8 
2.2 

8.2 

10.3 
6.1 
6.7 

51.1 
8.5 

13.1 
2.0 
5.3 
6.0 
9.5 

12.7 
7.6 
3.9 

17.0 
2.5 
2.7 

2.7 
3.6 
2.3 
4.2 
19.9 
2.4 
6.3 
1.4 
2.0 
1.8 
2.0 
3.8 
2.7 
3.2 
7.6 
2.3 
3.0 

2.5 
1.8 
6.6 
4.9 
1.8 
2.9 
1.7 
1.7 
2.6 
1.3 
1.9 
5.5 
2.7 
3.5 
5.6 
1.2 
2.1 

2.2 
1.6 
3.1 
3.8 
2.2 
3.2 
2.9 
1.9 
2.4 
1.2 
1.7 
5.6 
3.0 
4.3 
5.7 
.9 
2.8 

2.5 
2.0 
8.2 
7.1 
5.8 
3.6 
2.6 
2.0 
1.7 
1.1 
1.0 
4.6 
3.4 
4.6 
5.7 
.8 
3.4 

2.5 
2.7 
3.9 
2.2 
3.1 
5.9 
1.7 
1.9 
1.7 
2.0 
2.2 
5.8 
3.4 
5.4 
6.4 
1.6 
3.2 

3.8 
2.3 
3.5 
1.8 
1.9 
5.5 
2.3 
1.8 
1.8 
1.9 
5.5 
4.8 
3.7 
5.4 
6.4 
2.3 
2.2 

1.8 
1.4 
3.6 
1.4 
6.3 
5.7 
1.6 
1.5 
.8 
2.7 
2.2 
4.5 
3.1 
4.2 
6.8 
1.0 
4.0 

3.4 
3.6 

13.1 
4.3 

17.1 

10.3 
2.6 
2.1 
1.9 
4.1 
3.0 
8.8 
4.2 
5.9 

11.2 
1.2 
6.7 

4.3 

Food  and  beverages 

8  2 

Textiles 

Leather 

Rubber 

Forest  products -_      

7.1 

3.6 

21.0 

7.5 

Paper 

2.8 
3.9 

Chemicals 

Stone,  clay,  and  glass.. 

Metals 

Mining 

3.3 
3.1 
3.1 
13.8 

Trade 

5  2 

Service 

5.9 

Construction 

Public  utilities.... 

Finance 

13.3 

.8 

7.1 

J  The  deduction  of  prior  years'  losses  expired  with  the  year  1932. 
Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income. 


Table  9. — Deductions  for  prior  years'  loss  as  percent  of  taxable  net  income,  19Sl-t 
by  size,  classes  and  industries 

[Net  income  returns  only] 

PART  I.  1931  (2-YEAR  CARRY-OVER  PERMITTED) 


Manufacturing  (including 
miscellaneous  manufactur- 

ing)-. 

Food  and  beverages 

Tobacco.  _- 

Textiles 

Leather 

Rubber 

Forest  products 

Paper 

Printing. 

Chemicals 

Stone,  clay,  and  glass 

Metals 

Mining-. 

Trade 

Service 

Construction 

Public  utilities 

Finance 

All  corporations  (including 
agriculture  and  miscella- 
neous)  


Under 
$50 


8.7 
4.0 
5.8 
13.7 
12.5 
4.1 
16.5 
3.4 
7.4 
8.0 
8.5 
11.5 
13.4 
7.9 
8.5 
18.8 
7.0 
6.7 


8.6 


Size  classes  (based  on  total  assets  in  thousands) 


$50- 
$100 


10.2 

7.9 

27.4 

16.0 

27.6 

5.1 

12.1 

6.6 

2.9 

8.1 

8.8 

13.3 

8.3 

10.6 

10.0 

20.6 

8.8 

6.4 


$100- 
$250 


6.3 

14.5 
22.7 
47.6 

n.3 

6.4 
4.6 

11.7 
7.8 
7.2 

12.3 
9.1 
7.0 

17.4 
7.5 
6.3 


8.8 


$250- 
$500 


5.5 
4.5 
2.2 

12.6 

16.3 
3.8 

10.7 
4.6 
4.3 
8.7 
8.3 
6.9 

12.2 
6.8 
5.3 

12.7 
3.7 
8.4 


7.6 


$500- 
$1,000 


6.3 

6.1 

0) 
12.2 

9.6 
30.9 


7.0 
6.8 
6.2 
9.6 
6.6 
4.6 

12.9 
1.4 

10.0 


7.3 


$1,000- 
$5,000 


4.5 

2.7 

.4 

10.3 

3.3 
16.2 

5.0 

2.4 

3. 

4. 


5.7 


$5,000- 
$10,000 


3.8 
.8 

(1) 

34.8 
4.7 

40.6 

22.5 
2.1 

0) 
1.1 
9.3 
6.6 

13.0 
.4 

18.3 
4.8 
1.2 


3.6 


$10,000- 
$50,000 


3.1 

5.7 
0) 
10.2 
0) 
(2) 
60.2 

2.4 
.7 


1.4 
13.6 
9.9 
3.2 
2.0 


Over 

$50,000 


1.0 
2.5 

0) 

(0 

0) 

13.2 

(') 

0) 

(') 
(8) 

9.4 

1.4 
4.8 
.1 
(') 

(0 

.4 
3.8 


1.1 


Total 


3.2 

3.5 

.1 

12.5 
4.0 

15.3 

10.0 
2.6 
2.0 
1.8 
4.1 
3.0 
8.5 
4.0 
5.8 

11.2 
1.2 
5.7 


3.6 


1  No  loss  claimed. 

2  No  corporation. 

2  Less  than  0.05  percent. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


159 


Table  9. — Deductions  for  prior  years'  loss  as  percent  of  taxable  net  income,  1981-82 
by  size,  classes  and  industries — Continued 


PART  II.  1932  (1-YEAR  CARRY-OVER  PERMITTED) 

Size  classes  (based  on 

total  assets  in  thousands) 

Under 
$50 

$50- 
$100 

$100- 
$250 

$250- 
$500 

$500- 
$1,000 

$1,000- 
$5,000 

$5,000- 
$10,000 

$10,000- 
$50,000 

Over 
$50,000 

Total 

■Manufacturing    (including 
miscellaneous  manufactur- 
ing)  - 

Food  and  beverages 

Tobacco  

21.5 
12.0 

7.8 
25.3 
16.7 
21.9 
33.2 

8.9 
25.2 
15.4 
31.8 
34.7 
16.4 
20.2 
16.1 
45.7 

9.4 
11.9 

18.0 

13.4 
8.7 
13.3 
17.5 
20.0 
5.7 
27.4 
10.6 
7.0 
8.5 
15.9 
22.4 
18.4 
13.7 
12.5 
30.9 
5.8 
7.9 

12.6 

8.6 

4.6 

1.5 

10.9 

13.0 

12.3 

11.0 

5.4 

6.7 

7.3 

9.4 

16.4 

8.9 

8.5 

5.7 

18.3 

4.5 

7.9 

8.3 

4.5 
2.9 
7.0 
5.2 
6.4 
5.4 

10.5 
3.5 
3.8 
3.7 

11.0 
6.6 

11.1 
6.0 
4.3 
8.0 
3.8 
8.9 

6.3 

4.2 
3.6 

12.2 
8.9 
2.1 

21.4 

4.1 

.3 

3.9 

2.1 

10.7 
4.3 
7.8 
6.4 
3.1 

10.7 
4.5 

10.9 

6.5 

3.3 

1.7 

.1 

8.9 

11.1 
2.7 
1.6 
3.5 
4.2 
1.4 
.3 
5.3 
7.5 
2.4 
4.9 
5.4 
1.3 

11.0 

4.6 

1.6 
2.4 

0) 
2.0 

0) 

78.0 

<'L 

(') 
1.0 

0) 
.7 
3.1 
4.6 

(1) 

7.5 
2.8 

1.6 
3.5 

0) 
2.7 

0) 

i 

6.7 
.2 

(•) 

0) 
.1 

2.3 
2.0 
15.1 
.1 
8.5 

2.4 

5.4 
14.6 

^8 

(») 

0) 
(0 
6.5 

?! 

91.6 
2.5 

.6 
6.6 

2.7 

4.3 
8.2 

Textiles 

3  5 

Rubber                

21  0 

Forest  products 

Paper         - 

7.5 
2  8 

Printing        .     

3.9 

Chemicals                    

3.3 

Stone,  clay,  and  glass 

Metals               --- 

2.9 
2.9 

Mining 

13.9 

Trade    

5.0 

Service 

4.9 

13.3 

Public  utilities 

.8 

6.5 

All   corporations    (including 
agriculture    and   miscella- 
neous) - -- 

4.0 

1  No  loss  claimed. 
» No  corporation. 

Source:  Computed  from  the  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue. 

Definition  of  terms:  Taxable  net  income  is  the  excess  of  receipts  over  deductions  less  tax-e.^empt  income 
a.  e.,  intercorporate  dividends  and  interest  on  government  securities)  before  the  deduction  for  prior  years' 
losses. 

Table  10. — Consolidated  returns  in  Federal  corporate  income  taxation;  number  of 
returns,  gross  income,  net  income,  and  Federal  tax,  by  industries,  1928-86 


PART  I.  NUMBER  OF  CONSOLIDATED  RETURNS  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

1928 

1929 

1930 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936 

Manufacturing    (including 
miscellaneous) 

3,237 

I      502 

357 
100 
54 
289 
105 
227 
405 
130 
830 
526 

1,731 
549 
198 
789 

2,121 

9,300 

(0 

443,  611 
2.1 

3,216 

498 

363 

96 

43 

278 

105 

228 

398 

140 

844 

509 

1,450 

554 

194 

806 

1,907 

8,754 
30, 112 
456, 021 

1.9 

3,277 

488 

384 
98 
48 
282 
107 
253 
409 
136 
837 
502 

1,520 
582 
187 
789 

1,982 

8,951 
32,  209 
463,036 

1.9 

3,093 
}      431 

20 
365 

96 

41 
253 

96 
257 
382 
145 
795 
469 
1,445 
526 
182 
774 
1,895 

8,495 
31,  307 
459,  704 

1.8 

2,542 
352 

15 
300 

69 

37 
206 

84 
224 
308 
100 
661 
425 
1,278 
551 
176 
637 
1,707 

7,426 
29,  232 

451,884 

1.6 

2,455 

f      308 

1        53 

15 

287 

75 

38 

195 

85 

213 

298 

102 

642 

397 

1.135 

533 

169 

639 

1,665 

7,101 
28,  589 
446, 842 

1.6 

201 
33 
5 

Food 

Beverages 

Textiles 

41 
8 
6 
7 
5 
4 

26 
3 

54 
7 

66 

41 
2 

76 

50 

445 

2,522 

469,  804 

.1 

Leather 

Rubber 

Forest  products 

Printing 

Stone,  clay,  and  glass.. . 
Metals 

Mining 

Trade 

Service 

Pubhc  utilities 

63 

98 

Finance 

All  corporations  (including 
miscellaneous) 

63 
0) 
477, 113 

(») 



98 

Number  of  subsidiaries 

All  active  returns 

0) 
478,857 

Consolidates  returns  as  per- 

(?) 

1  Not  available. 

»  Less  than  0.05  percent. 


160 


OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  10. — Consolidated  returns  in  Federal  corporate  income  taxation;  number  of 
returns,  gross  income,  net  income  and  Federal  tax,  by  industries,  1928-36 — Con. 


PART  II.  GROSS  INCOME  REPORTED  ON  CONSOLIDATED  RETURNS  AS  PERCENT 
OF  TOTAL  GROSS  INCOME  REPORTED  ON  ALL  RETURNS 


1928 

1929 

1930 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936 

Manufacturing    (including 

52.7 

20.7 
38.7 
79.7 
26.7 
40.0 
32.7 
69.3 
35.0 
62.7 
54.1 
21.3 
25.6 
10.3 
80.7 
45.1 

45.6 

57.2 

62.0 

23.1 
43.1 
81.7 
26.8 
42.0 
33.2 
78.6 
40.0 
67.3 
57.1 
22.0 
27.8 
14.6 
83.0 
20.8 

43.6 

60.0 

63.3 

23.4 
43.6 
84.2 
28.8 
43.2 
33.4 
85.2 
42.5 
66.5 
58.3 
25.7 
79.0 
15.3 
84.1 
19.8 

47.6 

56.7 

1    61.2 

35.0 
23.3 
44.1 
82.6 
63.3 
36.0 
34.6 
79.2 
45.5 
65.7 
60.8 
27.6 
34.3 
15.0 
84.9 
21.7 

46.7 

49.2 

53.7 

9.5 
15.9 
23.9 
82.8 
26.1 
33.9 
28.3 
76.6 
31.7 
57.9 
56.1 
21.5 
27.8 
15.5 
68.9 
19.0 

39.6 

46.3 
r    52.1 
\    22.2 
9.0 
15.5 
21.0 
77.6 
27.4 
31.7 
27.9 
70.6 
31.1 
57.4 
59.3 
19.1 
26.6 
13.7 
68.9 
17.1 

37.9 

7.6 

23.7 

.7 

Food 

Tobacco 

Textiles 

i.3 
2.3 
26.3 
1.7 
2.4 

Leather                    

Rubber     

Forest  products    . 

Paper 

Printing 

Chemicals 

Stone,  clay,  and  glass... 

Metals... 

1.6 

11.4 

.1 

5.5 

Mining 

Trade 

Service 

Construction     

Public  utilities 

6.4 

18  1 

Finance   .  . 

All  corporations  (including 
miscellaneous) . . 

PART  III.  TAXABLE  NET  INCOME  REPORTED  ON  CONSOLIDATED  RETURNS  AS 
PERCENT  OF  THE  TOTAL  TAXABLE  NET  INCOME  REPORTED  ON  ALL  NET 
RETURNS 


Manufacturing    (including 
miscellaneous) 

53.4 

■    50.7 

40.6 
49.2 
55.7 
30.6 
31.7 
35.9 
64.1 
41.9 
62.4 
54.4 
30.4 
28.6 
16.0 
78.6 
20.7 

47.6 

58.4 

54.8 

31.6 
53.5 
64.4 
27.1 
39.2 
34.6 
78.2 
44.9 
64.7 
56.4 
30.5 
36.3 
21.5 
79.6 
21.1 

5L1 

60.3 

56.0 

31.3 
64.4 
52.1 
17.6 
37.0 
26.9 
78.3 
48.1 
66.7 
47.7 
37.4 
39.2 
16.7 
78.1 
19.0 

52.5 

55.6 
}    66.1 
26.1 
30.5 
70.8 
69.8 
17.8 
20.4 
25.0 
64.2 
52.5 
72.1 
27.2 
48.2 
27.9 
11.1 
74.0 
15.1 

50.1 

23.1 
31.0 

3.2 

7.1 
13.5 
45.2 

3.2 

5.2 
13.1 
37.4 

1.2 
26.9 
17.6 
23.7 
18.2 

7.3 
32.7 

4.6 

23.3 

29.8 
f 

Food         

. 

13everages 

1     26.8 
6.2 
13.2 
17.2 
41.4 
23.6 
15.3 
16.1 
36.9 
18.4 
52.2 
14.3 
19.4 
18.9 
1.5 
38.8 
10.7 

27.9 

7.0 

Tobacco    -  — 

Textiles 

1.6 

LI 

3.6 

.8 

.6 

(') 

.4 
(0 

.9 

(0 

1.3 

7.8 

.1 

L2 

(0 

L6 

Leather     .. 

Rubber 

Forest  products 

Paper 

Chemicals 

Stone,  clay,  and  glass... 

Metals 

Mining 

Trade 

Service 

Public  utilities 

0.6 

8.3 

Finance 

All  corporations  (including 

PART  IV.  FEDERAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAXES  REPORTED  ON  CONSOLIDATED 
RETURNS  AS  PERCENT  OF  TOTAL  FEDERAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAXES  RE- 
PORTED  ON  ALL  RETURNS 


Manufacturing    (including 

miscellaneous) 

Food 

Beverages 

Tobacco 

Textiles 

Leather 

Rubber 

Forest  products 

Paper 

Printing 

Chemicals 

Stone,  clay,  and  glass.. 
Metals 

Mining 

Trade 

Service... 

1  Less  than  0.05  percent. 


54.6 

51.9 

30.4 
51.4 
57.4 
32.2 
31.7 
37.9 
64.7 
43.4 
63.0 
64.7 
33.9 
32.5 


58.9 

52.3 

32.7 
57.1 
65.4 
28.7 
39.7 
36.7 
78.7 
46.4 
64.1 
58.9 
35.3 
40.5 


61.8 

67.5 

35.3 
67.6 
51.7 
19.9 
38.1 
28.3 
79.1 
58.1 
67.6 
50.4 
44.5 
44.9 


57.7 


26.1 
34.9 

75.7 
67.6 
20.9 
20.8 
26.2 
65.2 
55.0 
74.4 
29.8 
57.4 
33.1 


22.2 
27.2 

3.3 

8.2 
12.9 
33.7 

2.8 

5.6 
12.6 
37.2 

L4 
28.7 
10.9 
25.3 
17.6 


30.5 
27.8 
27.3 

6.7 
13.4 
18.0 
41.5 
23.9 
15.8 
16.7 
37.6 
18.9 
53.0 
14.6 
19.8 

1.5 


5.0 

17.0 

.2 


15.7 
7.0 

30.5 
2.0 
3.0 

(') 
3.7 


1.6 
(') 

7.6 
30.9 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


161 


Table  10. — Consolidated  returns  in  Federal  corporate  income  taxation;  number  of 
returns,  gross  income,  net  income  and  Federal  tax,  by  industries,  1928-36 — Con. 

PART  IV.  FEDERAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAXES  REPORTED  ON  CONSOLIDATED 
RETURNS  AS  PERCENT  OF  TOTAL  FEDERAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAXES  RE- 
PORTED ON  ALL  RETURNS— Continued 


1928 

1929 

1930 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936 

Construction. 

18.5 
79.4 
22.2 

49.9 

24.8 
80.2 
22.2 

62.9 

19.2 
79.1 
21.2 

55.9 

12.2 
75.4 
14.5 

54.3 

3.8 
33.8 
4.1 

23.5 

19.4 
40.0 
11.3 

28.6 

1.2 
2.9 

0) 

Public  utilities. 

Finance .... 

0.7 

7.9 

All  corporations  (including 
miscellaneous) 

1  Less  than  0.05  percent. 

Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 


Table    11. 


■Comparison    of  corporations  filing   consolidated   and   unconsolidated 
returns  in  1933  and  1934  by  industries 


PART  I.  MAJOR  INDUSTRIES 


1 

tJO 

a 

'S 

S 

1 

.1 

> 

1 

1 

6 

1 

i 

C3 

a 

< 

A.  Taxable    net    income   as  percent   of  corporate 
receipts: 
1.  Consolidated  corporations: 

(a)  All  returns  (net  and  no  net) : 

1933 

2.7 
3.8 

0.9 
3.9 

1.8 
2.4 

1.5 
3.2 

0.2 
2.4 

3.5 
5.3 

2.C 

6.2 

2.6 

1934 

4.0 

Increase  or  decrease 

1.1 

3.0 

.6 

1.7 

2.2 

L8 

4.2 

1.4 

(6)  Net  returns  only: 
1933 

4.4 
6.0 

5.9 
9.1 

2.8 
3.2 

5.7 
5.2 

L3 
6.0 

9.7 
12.0 

7.3 
15.2 

5.1 

1934.   

6.8 

Increase  or  decrease 

L6 

3.2 

.4 

-.5 

4.7 

2.3 

7.9 

L7 

2.  Unconsolidated     corporations: 
(a)  All  returns: 

1933    .               

5.4 
5.4 

7.7 
9.7 

L8 
2.0 

2.4 
3.1 

2.5 
2.6 

12.2 
12.2 

3.6 
5.1 

4.1 

1934 

4.3 

Increase  or  decrease 

2.0 

.2 

.7 

.1 

1.5 

.2 

(b)  Net  returns  only: 
1933 

8.2 
7.6 

16.0 
16.4 

2.9 
2.9 

7.4 
7.6 

6.7 
5.6 

18.6 
18.8 

9.6 
14.4 

7.1 

1934.              .. 

6.  a 

Increase  or  decrease 

-.6 

.4 



.2 

-11 

.2 

4.8 

-.a 

3.  All  corporations  (consolidated  and  uncon- 
solidated) : 
(a)  All  returns: 

1933...    

4.1 
4.6 

3.6 
6.2 

1.8 
2.1 

2.2 
3.1 

2.2 
2.6 

6.2 
7.3 

3.4 
5.3 

3.5 

1934                                      

4.2: 

Increase  or  decrease 

.5 

2.6 

.3 

.9 

.4 

1.1 

1.9 

.7 

(6)  Net  returns  only: 

1933                              

6.5 
6.9 

12.8 
12.6 

2.9 
3.0 

7.0 
6.7 

6.3 
5.6 

13.7 
14.6 

10.3 
14.3 

6.4 

1934                                      

6.S 

.4 

-.2 

.1 

-.3 

-.7 

1.1 

1 

4.0 

.4 

— 

162 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table    11. — Comparison   of  corporations  filing   consolidated   and   unconsolidated 
returns  in  1933  and  1934  by  industry — Continued 


PART  I.  MAJOR  INDUSTRIES— Continued 


CUD 

a 

1 

"3 

'5 

s 

1 

a 
o 

1 
§ 

.2 

3 
.2 

§ 

0 

< 

B.  Federal  taxes  as  percent  of  taxable  net  income 
(net  returns  only) : 
1.  Consolidated  corporations: 

1933-    -. 

14.5 
13.9 

14.5 
13.8 

14.5 
14.0 

14.6 
14.2 

14.5 
13.8 

14.5 
13.8 

14.7 
13.9 

14.5 

1934                          .... 

13.9 

Increase  or  decrease 

-.6 

-.7 

-.5 

-.4 

-.7 

-.7 

-.8 

-.6 

2.  Unconsolidated  Corporations: 

1933 _. 

14.1 
14.0 

14.2 
14.1 

14.2 
14.0 

14.2 
14.1 

14.6 
14.4 

13.8 
13.8 

13.9 
13.9 

14.0 

1934     -                        __. 

14.0 

Increase  or  decrease 

-.1 

-.1 

-.2 

-.1 

-.2 

1 

PART  II.  MANUFACTURING  INDUSTRIES 

1 

> 

1 

4.1 
5.1 

1 

2 
1 

1 

1.0 
1.7 

2.0 
2.8 

1 

2.2 
4.3 

1 
1 

£ 

2.5 
5.4 

2.3 
4.0 

n 

g-3, 

O 

'3 

A.  Taxable  net  imcome  as  percent  of 
corporate  receipts: 
1.  Consolidated  corporations: 
(a)  All  returns: 

1933. 

1934 

1.9 
2.6 

13.2 
13.5 

3.7 
1.9 

3.9 
2.2 

2.9 
7.0 

3.2 
4.3 

Increase  or  de- 
crease  - 

.7 

.3 

1.0 

5.0 
6.0 

1.0 

-1.8 

6.4 
4.5 

-1.7 

.7 

.8 

2.1 

6.0 
7.0 

2.9 

1.7 

4.1 

1.1 

(6)  Net  returns: 

1933 

1934 

2.3 
2.9 

.6 

5.5 

4.7 

1 

14.9 
15.6 

6.2 
3.5 

-2.7 

2.9 
3.5 

.6 

6.2 
6.6 

.4 

3.7 
8.3 

3.8 
9.9 

4.2 
9.3 

5.1 

6.4 
6.3 

Increase  or  de- 
crease  

.7 

-1.9 

4.5 
2.9 

1.0 

4.6 

6.1 

-.1 

2.  Unconsolidated  corporations: 
(a)  All  returns: 

1933 

1934 

12.1 
8.7 

7.2 
9.5 

5.0 
3.7 

4.9 
3.6 

2.4 
2.4 

5.6 
6.9 

5.0 
6.5 

9.3 
9.6 

5.7 
7.0 

3.9 
5.2 

Increase  or  de- 
crease  

-.8 

-3.4 

2.3 

-1.6 

-1.3 

-1.3 

1.3 

1 
1.5|      .2 

1.3 

1.3 

(6)  Net  returns: 

1933..-. 

1934 

8.1 
6.1 

15.2 
11.0 

8.0 
9.8 

6  4 

4.7 

6.6 
5.3 

6.9 

5.7 

5.4 
5.2 

7.7 
8.6 

•9 

8.8 
9.3 

13.7 
11.6 

10.2 
10.4 

7.9 

7.7 

Increase  or  de- 
crease  

-2.0 

-4.2 

1.8 

-1.7 

,-1.3 

-1.2 

-.. 

.5 

4.3 
6.2 

-2.1 

.2 

-.2 

3.  All  corporations: 

(a)  All  returns: 

1933 

3.6 
3.5 

12.4 
9.8 

6.9 
9.0 

4.4 
2.7 

4.8 
3.4 

1.9 
2.1 

2.3 
2.5 

1     4.5 
6.1 

4. 3     4. 8 
5.5     7.0 

1.2|    2.2 

2.7     8.1 
10.7,  10.0 

1    8.o'     1.9 

3.5 

1934 

4.6 

Increase  or  de- 
crease  

-.1 

-2.6 

2.1 

-1.7 

-1.4 

.2 

•2 

1.6 

1.9 

1.1 

(6)  Net  returns: 

1933 

1934 

Increase  or  de- 
crease.  

4.8 
4.2 

1 

!-.6 

15.1 
12.1 

-3.0 

7.8 
9.5 

1.7 

6.4 

;     4.7 

-1.7 

6.5 
5.0 

'-1.5 

4.4 
4.0 

-.4 

5.6 
5.6 

7.4 
8.2 

.8 

7.3 

j     9.0 

! 

I     1.7 

7.1 
6.8 

-.3 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


163 


Table    11. —Comparison   of  corporations  filing   consolidated   and   unconsolidated 
returns  in  1933  and  1934  by  industrij — Continued 


PART  II.  MANUFACTURING  INDUSTRIES- 

-Continued 

1 

1 

> 
PQ 

1 

1 

® 

.a 

1 

'6 

¥ 

o 

s. 

Ah 

1 

d 

i 

1 

B.  Federal  taxes  as  percent  of  taxable 
net  income  (net  returns  only) : 
1.  Consolidated  corporations: 

1933 

1934 

14.5 
14.1 

14.5 
14.7 

14.5 
13.8 

14.4 
14.0 

14.8 
14.0 

14.4 
14.2 

14.6 
13.8 

14.6 
14.0 

14.5 
13.9 

14.5 
13.8 

14.5 
13.8 

14.5 
13.8 

Increase  or  decrease 

-' 

.2 

-.7 

-.4 

-.8 

-.2 

14.4 
14.0 

-.4 

-.7 

-.6 

-.6 

-.7 

-.7 

-.7 

2.  Unconsolidated  corporations: 

1933 

1934 

14.1 
14.0 

-.1 

14.4 
14.2 

13.8 
13.8 

14.1 
14.0 

14.1 
13.9 

14.3 
14.0 

-.3 

14.1 
14.0 

13.9 
13.9 

14.0 
14.0 

14.0 
13.9 

14.0 
14.0 

Increase  or  decrease 

- 

-.1 

-.2 

-.1 

-.1 

—- 

Note. — All  corporations  filing  consolidated  returns  in  1933  are  included  as  consolidated  corporations. 
In  1934  the  great  majority  of  corporations  filed  returns  on  unconsolidated  basis,  the  only  exceptions  being 
railroads  and  corporations  whose  fiscal  years  exempted  them  from  the  provisions  of  the  1934  Revenue  Act. 

Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  income. 

Table  12. — Industrial  trends  in  the  operation  of  the  Federal  taxes  on  corporate 
income,  1926-36  {net  returns  only) 

PART  I.  TAXES  AS  PERCENT  OF  COMPILED  NET  PROFITS 


Manufacturing 

Food. 

Beverages 

Tobacco 

Textiles 

Leather 

Rubber 

Forest  products 

Paper... 

Printing 

Chemicals 

Stone,  clay,  and  glass. 

Metals 

Mining 

Trade 

Service. 

Construction 

Public  utilities 

Finance 


1926 


11.8 

8.5 

8.5 

8.1 

12.0 

12.4 

6.6 

12.0 

12.1 

11.4 

10.5 

12.6 

12.5 

11.0 

11.5 

ILl 

10.9 

10.6 

8.3 


1927      1928 


11.7 
12.1 
12.1 
12.3 
11.6 
12.1 
11.2 

n.7 

12.0 
11.1 

9.8 
12.6 
12.4 
11.1 
11.3 
10.8 
10.2 
10.2 

8.3 


10.3 
10.8 
10.2 
11.3 
10.7 
11.1 
9.5 
10.1 
10.5 
10.0 
8.7 
11.1 
11.0 
9.5 
9.2 
9.0 
9.4 
9.0 
7.7 


1929 


9.3 
9.8 
9.5 

10.4 
9.9 

10.3 
8.8 
9.3 
8.9 
9.7 
7.7 

10.1 
9.8 
9.1 
8.9 
8.1 
8.6 
7.6 
7.0 


1930     1931 


9.7 
10.5 
10.5 
11.3 
9.9 
10.9 
7.6 
9.3 
10.5 
8.8 
7.9 
10.7 
10.4 
9.4 
9.1 
8.5 
8.6 
7.7 
6.1 


9.7 
10.5 
10.1 
11.3 
8.9 
10.9 
8.7 
8.4 
10.3 
10.4 
7.9 
10.2 
10.0 
8.7 
9.3 
8.0 
8.6 
8.0 
6.2 


1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936  1 

n.2 

12.7 

12.4 

12.0 

15.2 

11.4 

13.1 

12.6 

14.2 

14.6 

12.8 

14.1 

13.8 

14.2 

16.5 

12.9 

11.6 

12.4 

11.7 

14.4 

10.9 

13.4 

13.2 

13.5 

16.4 

13.4 

13.7 

13.4 

13.8 

17.3 

9.8 

13.8 

13.7 

12.6 

16.2 

11.1 

13.7 

13.2 

12.8 

15.3 

12.4 

13.6 

13.3 

13.1 

15.9 

11.7 

12.5 

12.6 

12.7 

14.7 

9.3 

11.2 

11.0 

9.6 

12.1 

12.0 

13.0 

12.6 

12.6 

15.0 

11.7 

12.8 

12.4 

12.1 

15.5 

10.3 

13.0 

12.4 

11.7 

12.8 

12.0 

13.3 

13.1 

13.0 

15.3 

12.6 

13.4 

13.2 

13.2 

14.9 

10.7 

12.7 

13.1 

14.1 

15.7 

10.7 

11.1 

11.2 

11.3 

12.5 

7.5 

8.0 

6.0 

5.9 

6.0 

1937 


15.7 
14.2 
17.8 
14.7 
16.1 
15.1 
13.4 
15.4 
16.7 
14.8 
13.9 
15.7 
17.3 
14.1 
15.8 
15.1 
17.1 
13.1 
6.0 


»  Excludes  returns  not  subject  to  the  1936  revenue  act  because  of  fiscal  year. 

Definition:  Taxes  include  the  normal  corporate  income  tax  for  the  entire  period,  the  excess-profits  tax  for 
1933  and  subsequent  years,  and  the  surtax  on  undistributed  profits  for  1936.  Compiled  net  profits  Includes 
the  excess  of  compiled  receipts  over  compiled  deductions. 

Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 


164 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  12. — Industrial  trends  in  the  operation  of  the  Federal  taxes  on  corporate 
income.  1926-36  (net  returns  only) — Continued 

PART  11.  TAXES  AS  PERCENT  OF  COMPILED  NET  PROFITS  LESS 
INTERCORPORATE  DIVIDENDS  CREDIT  i 


1926 

1927 

1928 

1929 

1930 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936  2 

1937 

Manufacturing - 

Food 

12.8 
12.9 

12.6 
12.8 

11.3 
11.3 

10.3 
10.4 

11.2 
11.4 

11.0 
11.1 

12.6 
12.3 

13.7 
13.8 
14.2 
13.1 
13.6 
13.9 
14.0 
14.0 
13.9 
13.5 
13.6 
13.6 
13.6 
13.8 
13.6 
13.8 
14.0 
14.0 
10.8 

13.6 
13.8 
14.0 
13.3 
13.5 
13.7 
13.9 
13.6 
13.8 
13.5 
13.7 
13.5 
13.5 
13.6 
13.6 
13.6 
13.9 
14.0 
11.0 

14.1 
14.1 
14.5 
13.6 
14.0 
14.1 
14.7 
14.0 
13.8 
13.7 
13.8 
14.0 
14.4 
13.6 
14.7 
13.7 
14.0 
14.2 
11.8 

16.8 
15.8 
17.6 
15.4 
17.2 
17.6 
17.1 
16.2 
16.7 
16.3 
16.3 
16.2 
17.1 
15.2 
16.7 
15.4 
16.0 
16.0 
11.4 

17.2 
15.8 
18.4 

11.9 
9.1 
11.0 
9.7 
9.0 
10.9 
10.9 
11.3 
10.8 
11.0 
9.8 
9.2 
11.4 
9.8 
9.3 
7.7 

13.5 
11.2 
12.7 
10.2 
12.1 
12.9 
12.7 
12.8 
12.3 
12.4 
11.4 
11.2 
13.6 
12.8 
13.5 
9.7 

15.6 

Textiles-— 

Leather .- 

Rubber 

Forest  products 

Paper 

Printing 

12.3 
12.6 
12.8 
12.5 
12.8 
12.5 
12.9 
12.9 
12.9 
11.8 
11.6 
13.1 
11.9 
11.8 
10.0 

11.8 
12.3 
12.5 
12.3 
12.8 
12.5 
12.9 
12.9 
12.8 
12.3 
11.5 
13.1 
11.8 
11.7 
11.4 

10.9 
11.4 
11.4 
10.5 
11.5 
11.0 
11.5 
11.3 
11.3 
10.8 
9.9 
11.5 
9.5 
9.9 
9.5 

10.1 
10.5 
10.7 
9.8 
10.5 
10.2 
10.4 
10.3 
10.2 
10.1 
9.1 
10.5 
9.2 
9.4 
8.9 

10.2 
11.2 
10.6 

9.8 
11.3 
10.9 
11.4 
11.1 
11.3 
10.7 

9.9 
11.5 

9.8 
10.1 

8.4 

16.5 
15.7 
16.8 
16.2 
17.1 
16.4 

16.4 

Stone,  clay,  and  glass. 
Metals 

Mining 

16.3 
18.1 
16.3 

17.9 

Public  utilities           .  .  . 

15.6 

Trade 

Service 

Finance. 

16.7 
16.2 
11.8 

1  In  1936-37  the  intercorporate  dividend  credit  was  85  percent  of  dividends  received  from  domestic  corpo- 
rations subject  to  tax. 

2  Excludes  returns  not  subject  to  the  1936  Revenue  Act  because  of  fiscal  year. 


PART  III.  TAXES  AS  PERCENT  OF  TAXABLE  NET  INCOME  (BEFORE   DEDUCTION 
OF  PRIOR  YEARS'  LOSSES)  i 


1926 

1927 

1928 

1929 

1930 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936  2 

1937 

Manufacturing 

13.0 

12.9 
13.0 
12.7 

11.5 
11.0 
10.7 

10.4 
10.4 
10.5 

11.5 
11.5 
11.2 

11.3 
11.3 
10.6 

13.2 
12.6 
13.4 

14.2 
14.2 
14.4 

14.0 
14.0 
14.2 

14.4 
14.3 
14.6 

17.2 
16.2 
18.3 

17.9 

Food-       

16.2 

Beverages - 

12.9 

19.1 

Tobacco 

13.4 

13.1 

11.3 

11.0 

12.0 

12.0 

13.8 

13.8 

14.8 

13.8 

15.5 

15.8 

Textiles- 

12.7 

12.1 

11.4 

10.2 

10.5 

9.4 

12.3 

14.1 

14.0 

14.4 

17.5 

17.6 

Leather 

12.7 

12.3 

11.9 

10.6 

11.3 

11.1 

12.9 

14.2 

13.9 

14.2 

18.3 

16.1 

Rubber 

13.0 

12.6 

12.1 

10.8 

10.9 

9.8 

10.8 

14.4 

14.1 

14.8 

17.8 

17.3 

Forest  products 

12.7 

12.4 

10.4 

9.9 

10.0 

9.2 

12.6 

14.4 

14.0 

14.3 

16.9 

16.9 

Paper - 

13.0 

13.0 

11.9 

10.5 

11.5 

11.3 

13.5 

14.2 

14.0 

14.0 

17.5 

18.8 

Printing 

12.7 

12.7 

10.9 

10.3 

11.2 

11.1 

13.3 

14.0 

13.9 

14.1 

17.0 

17.3 

Chemicals 

13.2 

13.1 

11.6 

10.8 

11.8 

11.7 

13.5 

14.2 

13.9 

14.0 

17.3 

16.6 

Stone,  clay,  and  glass - 

13.1 

13.1 

11.8 

10.6 

11.3 

11.1 

13.3 

14.1 

13.8 

14.3 

16.6 

17.0 

Metals 

13.2 

13.2 

11.7 

10.3 

11.6 

11.4 

13.4 

14.3 

13.9 

14.7 

17.1 

19.0 

Mining 

12.6 
12.1 

12.6 
11.9 

11.  1 
10.1 

10.3 
9.3 

11.1 
9.9 

10.1 
9.9 

11.9 
13.1 

14.2 
14.3 

14.0 
14.1 

14.1 
14.2 

15.7 
16.6 

17.2 

Trade 

17.4 

Service 

11.9 

11.7 

10.0 

9.4 

10.1 

9.4 

13.0 

14.3 

14.1 

14.3 

16.5 

16.9 

Construction 

11.8 
13.3 
12.0 

11.7 
13.3 
11.9 

10.1 
11.7 
10.8 

9.3 
10.6 
10.1 

10.1 
11.7 
10.3 

9.5 
11.7 
9.7 

11.9 
13.9 
12.7 

14.6 
14.1 
14.0 

14.4 
13.8 
13.9 

15.2 
13.9 
14.2 

17.3 
15.7 
17.3 

19.0 

Public  utilities 

15.8 

Finance 

18.2 

1  Taxable  net  income  includes  compiled  net  profits  less  tax-exempt  income. 
*  Excludes  returns  not  subject  to  the  1930  revenue  act  because  of  fiscal  year. 

Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


165 


Table   12.^ — Industrial  trends  in  the  operation  of  the  Federal  taxes  on  corporate 
income,  1926-86  Cnet  returns  only) — Continued 

PART  IV.  TAXES  AS  PERCENT  OF  TAXABLE  NET  INCOME  (AFTER  DEDUCTION 
OF  PRIOR  YEARS'  LOSSES)  i 


1926 

1927 

1928 

1929 

1930 

1931 

1932 

Manufacturing                    

13.3 
13.2 

13.2 
13.3 
13.0 
13.2 
13.1 
13.3 
13.4 
12.9 
13.3 
12.9 
13.3 
13.2 
13.3 
13.2 
12.3 
12.3 
12.4 
13.3 
12.4 

11.8 
11.8 
11.7 
11.4 
11.8 
12.0 
12.1 
11.5 
12.0 
11.2 
12.0 
11.9 
12.1 
11.7 
10.5 
10.6 
10.7 
11.9 
11.2 

10.9 
10.7 
10.7 
11.0 
10.6 
10.8 

n.o 

10.5 
10.9 
10.5 
11.0 
10.8 
10.9 
10.8 

9.7 
10.0 

9.9 
10.9 
10.4 

11.7 
11.7 
11.5 
12.0 
10.9 

n.5 

11.6 
10.6 
11.7 

n.3 

11.9 
13.6 
11.8 
11.6 
10.2 
10.6 
10.8 
11.9 
10.7 

11.7 
11.7 
11.3 
12.0 
10.9 
11.6 
11.8 
10.3 
1L6 
11.4 
11.9 
1L5 
11.8 
11.1 
10.4 
10.0 
10.6 
11.8 
10.3 

13  8 

Food 

13  8 

Beverages 

13  7 

Tobacco 

13.5 
13.1 
13.2 
13.3 
13.1 
13.3 
12.9 
13.4 
13.2 
13.4 
13.3 
12.4 
12.4 
12.5 
13.4 
12.3 

13  8 

Textiles 

13.2 
13  3 

Leather 

Rubber 

13  7 

Forest  products 

13  7 

Paper 

13  9 

Printing.   .      . 

13.8 

Chemicals     .    .  .. 

14  0 

Stone,  clay,  and  glass 

13  7 

Metals.  -  --  - --- - 

13.9 

Mining 

13  8 

Trade 

13.8 

14.6 

Construction 

13  7 

Public  utilities .  -..  .    

14.0 

Finance                                  -      .  . 

13.7 

1  No  deduction  for  prior  years'  losses  was  permitted  in  193-3-37. 
Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 


Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments  as  percent  of  profits  of 
corporations  of  varying  size,  1931-37 


Table  13 

NORMAL  TAX  AS  PERCENT  OF  COMPILED  NET  PROFITS  i 


Size  classes  (000  omitted) 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936 

1937 

Under  $50 

2.8 
5.2 
7.4 
9.0 
9.4 
9.7 
9.9 
9.2 

}8.. 

10.8 
11.5 
11.8 
11.9 
12.0 
11.1 
11.1 
10.9 

9.7 

13.4 
13.4 
13.2 
13.0 
12.8 
12.5 
12.2 
11.5 

10.6 

13.5 
13.5 
13.3 
13.1 
12.7 
12.2 
11.8 
11.3 

8.9 

13.5 
13.5 
13.2 
12.9 
12.6 
11.9 
11.4 
10.9 

8.1 

10.0 
10.4 
10.7 
11.5 
12.0 
12.0 
11.7 
11.2 
f  9.9 
18.9 

9.5 

$50  to  $100         .          -                                         - 

10.2 

$100  to  $250 

10.8 

$250  to  $500 -       

11.5 

$500  to  $1,000 

11.8 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

12.0 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

11.7 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

11.7 

$.50,000  to  $100,000 

10.8 

Over  $100,000 

9.3 

NORMAL  TAX  AS  PERCENT  OF  COMPILED  NET  PROFITS  2   LESS  TAX  CREDIT  FOR 
INTERCORPORATE  DIVIDENDS 


Under  .$50 

2.9 
5.3 
7.6 
9.4 
10.0 
10.5 
10.8 
10.6 

}l0.5 

10.9 
11.7 
12.2 
12.3 
12.7 
12.1 
12.3 
12.3 

12.0 

13.6 
13.5 
13.5 
13.3 
13.3 
13.2 
13.0 
12.9 

12.7 

13.6 
13.6 
13.5 
13.4 
13.3 
13.1 
13.0 
12.9 

12.1 

13.6 
13.6 
13.5 
13.3 
13.2 
13.0 
12.9 
12.8 
12.1 

10.3 
10.7 
11.5 
12.4 
13.1 
13.7 
14.0 
14.0 
ri3.9 
\13.8 

9.8 

$50  to  $100 .  _                   .      - 

10.4 

$100  to  $250 

11.4 

.$250  to  $500 

12.3 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

13.0 
13.7 

$5,000  to  $10,000                                               .              . 

14.1 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

$50,000  to  $100,000     .     .                         .              .     

14.2 
14.5 

Over  $100,000 

14.3 

NORMAL  TAX  AS  PERCENT  OF  NORMAL  TAX  NET  INCOME   (I.  E.,  PROFITS  LESS 
TAX  CREDITS  FOR  INTERCORPORATE  DIVIDEND  2  AND  GOVERNMENT  INTEREST) 


Under  .$50                                                                             .      -- 

2.9 

5.3 

7.7 

9.6 

10.3 

11.0 

11.4 

11.3 

}n.2 

10.9 
11.8 
12.4 
12.6 
13.1 
12.8 
13.1 
13.2 

13.0 

13.7 
13.7 
13.7 
13.7 
13.6 
13.7 
13.7 
13.6 

13.6 

13.7 
13.7 
13.7 
13.7 
13.6 
13.6 
13.5 
13.4 

12.9 

13.7 
13.7 
13.7 
13.7 
13.6 
13.5 
1.3.4 
13.3 

10.3 
10.8 
11.6 
12.7 
13.5 
14.4 
14.8 
14.8 
/14.8 

9.8 

$50  to  $100 .._     

10.5 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

11.4 
12.6 

$500  to  $1,000    —     _-- 

13.5 

$1,000  to.$5,000                                                                              -  - 

14.4 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

14.9 

$10,000  to  $50,000     .                                                      

15.0 

$50,000  to  $100,000                                                                    

15.4 

Over  $100,000    .  .        _      

12-5    115.8 

15.5 

... 

1  Compiled  net  profits  includes  the  excess  of  compiled  receipts  over  compiled  deductions. 

2  In  1936-37  the  intercorporate  dividend  credit  was  85  percent  of  dividends  received  from  domestic  cor- 
porations subject  to  tax. 

Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income. 

262698 — 41— No.  9 12 


166 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  IS-A.— Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments,   1931-37,   by  size  of  cor- 
porations and  industries 

[Net  income  returns  only] 

(Computed  from  the  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue.  Federal  in- 
come taxes  include  the  normal  corporation  income  tax,  the  excess-profits  tax  since  1933,  and  the  surtax  on 
undistributed  profits  for  1936-37.  Compiled  net  profits  include  the  excess  of  compiled  receipts  over  com- 
piled deductions  before  the  payment  of  Federal  income  taxes.  Taxable  net  income  includes  compiled  net 
profits  less  tax-exempt  income.  In  1936, 15  percent  of  dividends  received  on  stock  of  domestic  corporations 
were  included,  whereas  previously  100  percent  was  excluded  as  tax-exempt  income) 

Manufacturing 


Size  classes  based  on  total  assets  (in  thousands) 


1931     1932 


1935      1936      1937 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  com- 
piled net  profits 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000.- 
$5,000  to  $10,000- 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500to$l,OdO---- 
$1,000  to  $5,000-- 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50.000 


.3.1 

10.4 

14.2 

14.3 

14.7 

16.0 

6.0 

11.4 

14.3 

14.3 

14.6 

14.5 

8.5 

12.0 

14.1 

14.0 

14.4 

15.3 

10.0 

12.3 

14.0 

13.8 

14.3 

16.1 

m.5 

12.4 

13.8 

13.6 

14.0 

16.7 

10.7 

12.2 

13.4 

13.1 

13.5 

16.7 

10.8 

12.3 

13.3 

12.9 

12.7 

16.3 

10.1 

11.9 

12.6 

12.3 

12.4 

14.7 

9.3 

10.1 

11.6 

11.1 

9.9 

13.1 

14.6 
15.1 
16.0 
16.9 
17.6 
17.9 
17.6 
16.1 
14.2 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  tax- 
able net  income 


3.1 

10.6 

14.6 

14.5 

14.8 

16.0 

6.1 

11.6 

14.6 

14.4 

14.8 

14.6 

8.7 

12.3 

14.5 

14.3 

14.6 

15.3 

10.4 

12.8 

14.4 

14.2 

14.6 

16.1 

11.0 

13.1 

14.3 

14.1 

14.5 

16.7 

11.4 

13.2 

14.1 

14.0 

14.4 

16.8 

11.6 

13.5 

14.1 

13.9 

14.1 

16.4 

11.7 

13.0 

14.1 

13.8 

14.2 

14.8 

11.9 

13.2 

14.2 

13.8 

14.4 

13.1 

15.2 
15.9 
16.9 
17.8 
18.8 
19.3 
19.3 
18.0 
16.8 


Food 


Size  classes  based  on  total  assets  (in  thousands) 


1931  >   19321    1933 »     1934     1935     1936     1937 


Under  $50 

$50  to  .$100 --. 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  .$5,000- - - 
$5,000  to  $10,000-- 
$10,000  to  $50,000- 
Over  $50,000 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  com- 
piled net  profits 


4.6 
6.5 
9.0 
10.3 
10.5 
11.1 
11.4 
10.0 
10.8 


11.9 

14.4 

14.3 

14.5 

14.0 

12.1 

14.1 

14.1 

14.3 

14.1 

12.6 

14.3 

14.1 

14.4 

14.3 

12.4 

14.3 

13.9 

14.2 

15.4 

12.5 

14.0 

13.8 

14.0 

15.9 

12.7 

13.8 

13.  3 

13.6 

16.6 

12.4 

13.3 

13.0 

12.8 

15.6 

11.7 

13.6 

13.1 

12.4 

14.8 

10.7 

12.9 

11.1 

9.8 

13.2 

14.1 
14.2 
14.5 
15.4 
15.8 
16.8 
16.3 
14.4 
12.4 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  tax- 
able net  income 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 .- 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1, 000--. - 
$1,000  to  $5,000-. 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  .$50,000 
Over  $50,000 


4.7 
6.6 
9.2 
10.8 
11.0 
11.7 
11.9 
11.3 
11.7 


12.0 

14.6 

14.5 

14.6 

14.0 

12.3 

14.4 

14.5 

14.6 

14.2 

12.8 

14.6 

14.4 

14.6 

14.2 

12.8 

14.  5 

14.3 

14.7 

15.4 

13.1 

14.3 

14.2 

14.5 

16.0 

13.5 

14.2 

14.1 

14.6 

16.7 

13.3 

14.0 

14.0 

14.1 

15.7 

13.4 

14.2 

13.9 

14.0 

14.9 

11.9 

14.2 

14.0 

14.0 

13.3 

14.7 
14.9 
15.2 
16.2 
16.8 
18.1 
17.9 
15.9 
15.7 


»  Beverages  are  included  as  part  of  food. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


167 


Table  13-A.— Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments,   1931-37,  by  size    of  cor- 
porations and  industries — Continued 


Beverages ' 


Size  classes  based  on  total  assets  (in  thousands) 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936 

1937 

Federal  income  taxes  as  percent- 
ages of  compiled  net  profits 

Under  $50 

14.5 
14.4 
14.6 
14.7 
14.3 
14.3 
13.2 
13.7 

14.4 
14.5 
14.6 
14.2 
13.6 
14.0 
1.3.2 
13.6 

14.9 
14.9 
14.4 
14.7 
13.9 
14.2 
14.0 
13.9 

13.8 
14.5 
15.6 
16.8 
17.1 
19.5 
19.4 
17.6 
10.5 

13.5 
14.9 
16.7 
16.4 
17.6 
18.9 
22.4 
19.0 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 . 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1.000 

$1,000  to  S5,000 . 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

$10,000  to  $50,000 ..       . 

Over  $50.000 

Federal  income  ta.xes  as  percent- 
ages of  taxable  net  income 

Under  $50 

14.6 
14.5 
14.7 
14.8 
14.6 
14.5 
14.1 
14.2 

14.6 
14.6 
14.7 
14.3 
14.0 
14.2 
14. 1 
13.9 

15.0 
15.0 
14.7 
K.7 
14.2 
14.7 
14.4 
14.6 

13.8 
14.5 
15.6 
16.8 
17.2 
19.5 
19.5 
17.8 
10.5 

13  9 

$50  to  $10(1 

15  5 

$100  to  $250-. 

17  4 

$250  to  $500     

17  0 

$500  to  $1.000. 

18  8 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

20  1 

$5,000  to  $10,000 - 

24  3 

$10,000  to  $50,000 - 

21  1 

Over  $50.000 

For  1931  and  1932  beverages  were  included  with  foods  in  Statistics  of  Income. 

Tobacco 


Size  classes  based  on  total  assets  (in  thousands) 


1931      1932      1933      1934      1935 


1937 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
compiled  net  profits 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1.000 

$1,000  to  $5,000.. 
.$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  $50.C»00 
Over  i?5('.000 


Under  $60 

$50to$10C' 

$100  to  .$250 

.$250  to  $500 

$500to$1.0C>0...- 
$1,000  to  $5.000.. 
.$5,000  to  $U',000. 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000    .  . 


6.8 

10.0 

14.5 

14.3 

15.4 

11.7 

3.2 

11.9 

14.8 

13.9 

14.4 

13.0 

9.5 

13.3 

13.6 

13.4 

14.3 

13.3 

10.3 

12.3 

14.0 

13.9 

13.7 

12.2 

11.3 

12.1 

12.8 

13.0 

14.8 

13.4 

11.3 

12.8 

13.0 

13.1 

13.8 

17.0 

11.7 

13.2 

12.8 

13.3 

12.9 

13.3 

11.2 

13.1 

13.2 

13.1 

13.1 

14.6 

11.4 

12.8 

10.9 

12.2 

11.2 

14.2 

11.5 
12.9 
13.0 
15.2 
16.1 
17.6 
18.4 
16.1 
14.4 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
taxable  net  income 


6.8 

10.0 

14.8 

15.6 

15.4 

11.7 

3.2 

11.1 

15.1 

13.7 

14.4 

13.0 

10.1 

13.6 

14.3 

13.8 

14.6 

13.3 

10.8 

13.2 

13.6 

14.1 

14.2 

12.4 

11.8 

12.2 

13.5 

15.0 

15.8 

13.8 

11.6 

13.7 

13.8 

1.3.8 

14.4 

17.0 

13.0 

13.8 

13.9 

13.7 

13.8 

13.3 

12.0 

14.0 

13.9 

13.7 

13.8 

14.7 

12.0 

13.7 

13.8 

13.7 

13.8 

14.2 

11.6 
15.7 
13.8 
17.1 
16.7 
19.1 
20.8 
17.7 
1.5.1 


168 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  13-A. — Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments,    1931-37,   by  size   of  cor- 
porations and  industries — Continued 

Textiles  (Including  Clothing) 


Size  classes  based  on  total  assets  (in  thousands) 


1931 


1932     1933 


1934 


1935      1936 


1937 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  com- 
piled net  profits 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000-. 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000-.  - - 
$1,000  to  $5,000-- 
$5,000  to  $10,000- 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


1.7 

9.5 

14.3 

14.4 

14.6 

14.6 

5.1 

10.8 

14.5 

14.2 

14.6 

14.7 

7.4 

11.6 

14.3 

14.1 

14.4 

15.8 

9.4 

12.4 

14.0 

13.8 

14.3 

16.7 

9.9 

11.9 

14.0 

13.5 

13.9 

17.4 

10.2 

11.1 

13.6 

13.3 

13.6 

17.4 

6.9 

10.4 

12.7 

12.5 

12.9 

18.3  1 

9.4 

10.8 

13.0 

12.7 

13.0 

16.0 

12.0 

0) 

12.6 

11.1 

12.0 

14.5 

14.8 
13.7 
15.1 
16.7 
16.9 
17.3 
17.2 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  tax- 
able net  income 


1.7 

9.6 

14.7 

14.5 

H.7 

14.6 

5.1 

11.0 

14.7 

14.4 

14.6 

14.7 

7.5 

11.9 

14.6 

14.2 

14.6 

15.8 

9.6 

12.8 

14.4 

14.3 

14.5 

16.7 

10.1 

]2.4 

14.4 

14.0 

14.3 

17.4 

10.7 

12.3 

14.2 

14.0 

14.4 

17.4 

7.8 

12.6 

13.8 

13.9 

14.2 

18.3 

10.8 

12.7 

13.8 

13.8 

14.4 

15.5 

12.0 

11.1 

14.1 

13.8 

13.7 

14.9 
1 

15.1 
15.5 
15.5 
17.2 
17.5 
18.4 
18.5 


Leather 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

.$2.50  to  $.500- 

$500  to  $1.000 

$1,000  to  $5,000... 
.$5,000  to  $10,000. . 
$10,000  to  $50,000. 
Over  $50,000 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  com- 
piled net  profits 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 -_. - 
$1,000  to  $5,000.. 
$5,000  to  $10,000- 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50.000 


3.1 

10.4 

11.9 

14.1 

12.0 

14.5 

14.3 

4.8 

10.8 

15.0 

14.4 

14.4 

13.9 

15.2 

7.1 

11.6 

14.1 

14.0 

14.4 

14.6 

16.2 

9.1 

11.9 

13.4 

13.8 

14.2 

15.2 

14.9 

11.8 

12.6 

14.0 

14.3 

14.1 

17.1 

15.7 

11.1 

10.0 

13.7 

13.2 

13.9 

17.7 

15.9 

10.9 

12.8 

14.0 

10.3 

13.2 

19.1 

15.4 

11.7 

12.3 

13.1 

13.2 

13.  5 

30.7 

12.0 

13.6 

13.7 

13.7 

13.7 

Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages 

of  tax- 

able  net  income 

3.1 

10.9 

15.1 

14.4 

14.6 

14.5 

14.3 

4.8 

10.8 

15.1 

14.5 

14.5 

14.0 

16.4 

7.2 

11.7 

14.5 

14.2 

14.6 

14.6 

16.6 

9.3 

12.2 

14.3 

14.1 

14.4 

15.3 

16.0 

12.  1 

12.8 

14.4 

11.5 

14.7 

17.3 

16.8 

11.5 

12.1 

14.4 

13.9 

14.3 

17.7 

16.8 

11.4 

13.8 

14.2 

13.7 

13.9 

19.2 

16.6 

12.0 

12.5 

13.8 

13.8 

13.7 

30.7 

12.0 

13.6 

13.7 

13.7 

13.7 

RusrER 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
compiled  net  profits 

Under  $50                                                                     ....... 

4.8 
5.8 

8.4 
12.3 
11.8 
12.4 
14.3 
11.2 

0) 

14.9 
15.1 
14.9 
14.6 
14.5 
13.4 
13.2 
12.9 
14.4 

13.9 
14.6 
14.1 
14.  1 
13.7 
13.0 
13.5 
12.9 
14.2 

14.2 
14.1 
14.5 
14.6 
14.7 
13.3 
10.6 
15.2 
8.4 

14.7 
12.7 
15.5 
18.3 
18.2 
16.7 
19.3 
17.2 
14.7 

17.0 

$50  to  $100 

14.2 

$100  to  $260  ""       -          

5.7 
10.7 
8.0 
9.6 
7.1 

14.8 

$250  to  .$500 

17.4 

.$500  to  $1,000                                  

19.4 

$1,000  to  $5,000                                                              -- 

18.2 

$5,000  to  $10.000 -..- 

$10,000  to  $.50,000 

19.8 
16.4 

Over  $50,000                                                                                --  - 

8.8 

9.8 

1  Not  computed. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


169 


Table  IS-A.^Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments,   1931-37,   hy  size  of  cor- 
porations and  industries — Continued 


Rubber— Continued 


Size  classes  based  on  total  assets  (in  thousands) 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936 

1937 

Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
taxable  net  income 

Under  $50 

4.8 
5.9 
6.3 

10.9 
8.0 

10.1 
7.1 

12.5 
12.3 
11.9 
12.8 
14.3 
13.1 
0) 

14.9 
15.1 
15.2 
14.7 
14.9 
14.2 
13.3 
14.3 
14.5 

13.9 
14.7 
14.3 
14.3 
13.8 
13.8 
13.8 
13.7 
14.6 

14.2 
14.5 
14.5 
14.9 
14.7 
14.5 
14.3 
15.7 
13.7 

14.0 
12.7 
15.5 
18.3 
18.2 
16.9 
19.3 
17.2 
14.7 

18.3 
14.6 
15.3 
18.4 
20.6 
19.3 
21.4 
18.6 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250. - 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000. 

$5,000  to  $10,000  

$10,000  to  $50,000 

Over  $50,000 

10.4 

11.3 

Forest  Products 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
compiled  net  profits 

Under  $50.. 

1.8 
5.9 
7.7 
8.5 
10.2 
10.7 
4.8 
1.8 

8.6 
9.9 
11.6 
11.6 
11.7 
12.3 
7.1 

14.4 
13.6 
14.0 
13.9 
13.8 
13.2 
13.1 
13.1 
13.7 

14.2 
14.5 
13.9 
13.6 
13.4 
12.9 
12.8 
13.1 
11.4 

14.9 
14.8 
14.4 
14.1 
14.1 
12.5 
9.3 
10.4 
10.7 

14.6 
14.4 
15.5 
14.7 
15.7 
15.5 
19.3 
10.8 
13.1 

14  8 

$50  to  $100 

15  0 

$100  to  $250 

15  5 

$250  to  $500 

15  7 

$500  to  $1,000    

16  1 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

15  9 

$5,000  to  $10,000 .. 

17  8 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

Over  $50,000 

Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
taxable  net  income 

Under  $50 

1.8 
6.0 
7.8 
8.9 
10.8 
11.3 
9.1 
4.9 

8.8 
10.1 
11.9 
12.1 
12.9 
13.5 
13.9 

14.8 
14.7 
14.4 
14.4 
14.4 
14.1 
14.8 
14.5 
14.5 

14.5 
14.6 
14.1 
14.1 
14.0 
13.9 
13.8 
13.8 
13.7 

15.0 
14.9 
14.6 
14.5 
14.7 
14.1 
13.7 
13.8 
13.8 

14.6 
14.4 
15.5 
14.8 
15.7 
15.6 
19.4 
10.  S 
13.3 

15.9 

$50  to  $100      ...     - 

16  0 

$100  to  $250— - 

16.4 

$250  to  $500 

16.9 

$500  to  $1,000 

17.4 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

17.5 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

20.0 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

Over  $50,000 

Paper 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000...- 
.$1,000  to  $5,000-. 
$5,000  to  $10,000- 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 --.- 
$1,000  to  $5,000. . 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  ,$50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
compiled  net  profits 


3.1 

12.2 

13.7 

14.2 

14.6 

13.9 

5.4 

11.6 

14.2 

13.9 

14.1 

14.3 

8.7 

12.fi 

14.2 

14.0 

14.4 

14.8 

10.4 

11.9 

14.3 

13.8 

13.9 

16.1 

10.8 

14.3 

13.7 

13.7 

13.7 

16.3 

11.0 

12.5 

13.5 

13.3 

12.9 

17.6 

11.4 

11.8 

13.6 

13.4 

13.1 

16.0 

9.6 

13.2 

13.3 

13.4 

12.8 

15.1 

9.4 

7.3 

14.3 

8.4 

10.0 

12.6 

14.5 
13.6 
15.6 
17.5 
17.4 
17.9 
16.4 
16.3 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
taxable  net  income 


3.1 

12.2 

13.9 

u.. 

14.8 

13.9 

5,  5 

11.7 

14.4 

14.2 

14.2 

14.5 

10,2 

12.7 

14.4 

14.2 

14.6 

14.8 

10.7 

13.0 

14.6 

14.2 

14.2 

16.1 

11.5 

15.0 

14.2 

14.3 

14.1 

16.4 

in,  8 

13.2 

14.2 

13.9 

14.0 

17.6 

11.8 

13.0 

14.1 

14.0 

14.1 

16.1 

11.7 

13.7 

13.9 

13.9 

13.9 

15.2 

12.4 

13.8 

14.0 

14.6 

14.4 

12.6 

15.3 
14.2 
16.5 

18.7 
18.7 
19.6 
17.7 
18.2 


'  Not  computed. 


170  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  13-A. — Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments,   1931-87, 
porations  and  industries — Continued 


hy 


\ZQ    of     COT- 


Pbinting 


Size  classes  based  on  total  assets  (in  thousands) 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 -_.- 
$1,000  to  $5,000- . 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000--.. 
$1,000  to  $5,000-. 
$5,000  to  $10,000- 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


1931 


1932     1933     1934     1935      1936     1937 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
compiled  net  profits 


2.7 

9.9 

14.1 

14.2 

6.2 

12.1 

13.8 

13.9 

8.8 

12.5 

13.6 

13.9 

10.3 

12.7 

13.7 

13.5 

10.8 

11.7 

12.9 

13.1 

10.9 

12.4 

12.7 

13.2 

110.1 

12.5 

13.0 

12.2 

10.7 

10.7 

11.6 

11.5 

10.6 

9.5 

9.2 

10.9 

14.5 
14.3 
14.1 
13.9 
13.4 
13.2 
12.1 
11.5 
11.0 


14.7 

13.5 

14.1 

14.8 

15.4 

16.7 

15.4 

12.3 

10.2 

14.0 
13.5 
14.7 
15.7 
16.0 
16.2 
15.0 
14.8 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
taxable  net  income 


2.7 

m> 

14.2 

14.5 

14.6 

.14.7 

6.4 

12.6 

14.2 

14.3 

14.5 

13.5 

9.2 

12.9 

14.0 

14.2 

14.5 

14.1 

10.8 

1.3.2 

14.2 

13.9 

14.3 

14.9 

11.5 

13.1 

14.0 

14.0 

14.2 

15.5  ! 

11.5 

13.2 

14.1 

14.0 

14.2 

16.8  1 

12.0 

13.8 

13.9 

1.3.8 

13.8 

15.4  ! 

11.9 

13.1 

14.0 

13.8 

13.8 

12.4  ' 

12.0 

13.9 

14.3 

13.8 

13.8 

10.4 

14.7 
14.2 
15.5 
16.7 
17.3 
17.9 
17.3 
18.5 


Chemicals  (Including  Petroleum) 


Under  $50- 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $.^,00 

$500  to  $1,000--.. 
$1,000  to  $5,000-. 
$5,000  to  $10,000- 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250- 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000. -. - 
$1,000  to  $5,000.. 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
compiled  net  profits 


4.0 
6.2 
8.9 
10.4 
10.4 
10.9 
11.1 
10.2 
9.7 


11.4 
12.1 
12.1 
12.7 
12.9 
12.4 
12.9 
12.5 
6.2 


14.0 
14.4 
14.1 
13.8 
13.6 
13.3 
13.7 
11.7 
8.7 


14.1 
14.1 
14.1 
13.8 
13.7 
12.8 
13.3 
11.9 
7.8 


14.7 
14.4 
14.2 
13.9 
13.7 
12.5 
12.6 
11.5 
5.8 


14.5 
14.5 
15.7 
15.7 
16.4 
15.8 
14.7 
13.9 
10.4 


13.7 
15.2 
16.1 
15.6 
16.7 
16.4 
15.4 
15.1 
14.4 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
taxable  net  income 


4.1 

11.4 

14.4 

14.2 

14.9 

14.5 

6.3 

12.4 

14.6 

14.3 

14.6 

14.6 

9.0 

12.5 

14.3 

14.3 

14.4 

15.7 

10.6 

13.0 

14.1 

14.3 

14.3 

15.7 

11.0 

13.4 

14.3 

14.2 

14.3 

16.5 

11.5 

13.4 

13.9 

14.0 

14.2 

15.9 

11.9 

13.7 

14.2 

13.8 

13.8 

14.7 

12.1 

13.9 

14.3 

13.8 

14.0 

14.2 

10.1 

13.4 

14.3 

14.0 

13.8 

10.4 

14.2 
16.1 
16.9 
16.5 
17.3 
18.4 
17.2 
16.9 
16.8 


Stone,  Clay,  and 

Glass 

Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
compiled  net  profits 

Under  $50  ... 

1.3 
6.0 
8.1 
9.5 
10.4 
10.2 
10.  ■> 
10.7 
10.2 

8.6 
11.2 
12.1 
11.5 
11.1 
12.6 
13.1 
11.6 
13.9 

14.3 
14.1 
12.5 
14.3 
13.6 
12.9 
13.5 
12.5 
13.8 

13.9 
14.3 
13.9 
13.8 
13.5 
13.2 
13.1 
11.8 
12.5 

14.6 
14.8 
14.1 
14.2 
13.9 
14.4 
11.0 
12.1 
12.1 

15.0 
14.4 
15.4 
16.0 
16.5 
15.9 
16.7 
13.9 
15.0 

H. 

$50  to  $100 

14.1 

$100  to  $250- 

15.2 

$250  to  $500 

16.5 

$500  to  $1,000 

17.4 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

17.0 

$5,000  to  $10,000 . 

16.5 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

15.0 

Over  $50,000 

Roughly  corrected  for  arithmetical  error  in  source. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  17][ 

Table  13-A. — Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments,   1931-37,   by  size  of  cor- 
porations and  industries — Continued 

Stone,  Clay,  and  Glass— Continued 


Size  classes  based  on  total  assets  (in  thousands) 


Under  50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000..-. 
$1,000  to  $5,000.. 
$5,000  to  $10,000- 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


1931 


1932 


1933 


1934 


1935     1936 


1937 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
taxable  net  income 


1.3 

8.7 

14.3 

14.2 

14.7 

15.0 

6.1 

11.6 

14.3 

14.5 

15.2 

14.4 

8.3 

12.4 

14.2 

14.3 

14.5 

15.4 

9.9 

12.0 

14.8 

14.3 

14.6 

16.1 

10.9 

12.1 

14.1 

14.0 

14.5 

16.6 

11.3 

13.7 

13.8 

13.8 

14.8 

16.0 

10.9 

13.8 

14.3 

13.9 

14.2 

16.7 

11.8 

13.8 

14.0 

13.8 

14.0 

14.1 

10.9 

13.9 

14.4 

13.7 

14.2 

15.  1 

15.7 
14.7 
16.0 
17.5 
18.5 
18.2 
18.2 
16.7 


Metals  (Including  Motor  Vehicles) 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000.. -- 
$1,000  to  $5,000.- 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Under  $50. 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000- -. - 
$1,000  to  $5,000-. 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  com- 
piled net  profits 


2.5 

8.8 

14.6 

14.6 

14.9 

15.1 

15.3 

5.9 

9.9 

14.5 

14.4 

14.9 

15.3 

15.4 

8.2 

10.9 

14.0 

13.9 

14.6 

16.2 

17.3 

10.1 

13.1 

13.9 

13.8 

14.4 

17.3 

18.7 

10.4 

12.5 

13.8 

13.7 

14.5 

18.3 

18.2 

10.4 

11.6 

13.8 

12.8 

13.7 

17.6 

18.6 

10.3 

11.9 

13.2 

12.9 

12.8 

16.9 

19.2 

11.6 

10.9 

12.2 

11.8 

12.5 

15.4 

17.4 

10.2 

12.2 

12.6 

11.8 

11.0 

14.4 

14.5 

Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  tax- 

able net  income 

2.5 

8.9 

14.7 

14.7 

15.0 

15.1 

6.0 

10.1 

14.8 

14.5 

15.0 

15.3 

8.3 

11.2 

14.4 

14.4 

14.8 

16.2 

10.5 

12.7 

14.4 

14.2 

14.8 

17.3  i 

11.0 

13.1 

14.3 

14.1 

14.4 

IS.  4  i 

11.6 

13.0 

14.0 

13.9 

14.5 

17.7  1 

11.2 

13.5 

14.1 

14.0 

14.2 

17.0 

11.6 

14.1 

14.2 

13.8 

14.4 

15.5 

11.8 

14.0 

14.3 

13.8 

14.9 

14.6  1 

15.7 
16.1 
18.6 
20.0 
19.4 
19.9 
21.0 
18.9 
17.8 


Mining 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
compiled  net  profits 

Under  $50 

5.7 
6.9 

8.5 
8.1 
10.1 
8.8 
8.4 
9.0 
9.1 

11.1 
11.0 
12.3 
11.8 
12.3 
10.9 
12.2 
12.5 
.6 

14.5 
14.7 
13.7 
14.0 
13.6 
13.4 
10.9 
12.5 
12.8 

14.1 
14.2 
14.8 
13.8 
13.5 
12.4 
12.2 
11.2 
11.9 

14.1 
14.1 
14.2 
13.9 
13.4 
11.9 
10.4 
10.8 
11.3 

12.7 
13.6 
13.8 
13.8 
14.0 
14.2 
14.2 
13.1 
11.1 

13.1 

$50to$100                                          

17.7 

$100  to  $250 

14.6 

$250to$500       

15.0 

$500  to  $1,000                                                                 

14.8 

$1,000  to  $5,000. 

15.0 

$5,000  to  $10,000                                  .              

15.5 

$10,000  to  $50  000 

15.5 

$50,000  and  over      

13.3 

Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of 
taxable  net  income 

Under  $50                                                                     

5.8 
7.1 
8.6 
9.8 
10.3 
10.4 
10.8 
11.6 
11.4 

n.2 

11.2 
12.5 
12.1 
12.6 
12.8 
13.4 
13.9 
1.2 

14.7 
14.8 
14.1 
14.4 
14.1 
14.6 
13.9 
13.9 
14.5 

14.5 
14.4 
14.2 
14.4 
14.4 
13.9 
14.0 
13.8 
13.7 

14.6 
14.4 
14.5 
14.5 
14.5 
14.1 
13.8 
13.9 
13.7 

12.7  1     13.5 

$50to  $100                                 

13.6 
13.8 
13.9 
14.1 
14.3 
14.3 
13.3 

16.3 

$100  to  $250                                                                 

15.5 

$250  to  $500                                                                      

15.7 

$500  to  $1,000                                

16.2 

$1,000  to  $5  000                                                          

17.1 

$5  000  to  $10  000                                                               .  

18.9 

$10,000  to  $50,000                     

18.1 

$50,000  and  over                                                   

11. 1        17.  2 

X72  OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  13-A. — Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments,   1931-37,   hy  size  of  cor- 
porations and  industries — Continued 


Trade 


Size  classes  based  on  total  assets  (in  thousands) 


1931      1932     1933     1934     1935     1936     1937 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of-com- 
piled  net  profits 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250- 

$250  to  $500. 

$500  to  $1,000.-.. 
$1,000  to  $5,000.. 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000.-.. 
$1,000  to  $5,000.. 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


2.2 

10.3 

14.5 

14.3 

.4.6 

.4.2 

4.8 

11.2 

14.1 

14.1 

14.3 

14.2 

7.4 

11.9 

14.1 

13.9 

14.0 

14.6 

9.3 

12.2 

13.4 

13.6 

13.9 

15.2 

10.1 

12.1 

13.5 

13.5 

13.7 

16.3 

10.3 

12.1 

13.3 

12.9 

13.1 

16.8 

10.8 

12.1 

13.1 

13.2 

12.8 

16.1 

10.4 

12.1 

12.0 

12.6 

11.8 

15.7 

11.1 

12.2 

13.2 

12.2 

12.6 

14.1 

14.3 
14.5 
15.1 
15.9 
16.7 
17.5 
16.2 
16.5 
14.3 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  taxable 
net  income 


2.3 

10.5 

14.7 

14.4 

14.7 

14.2 

4.8 

11.6 

14.4 

14.3 

14.5 

14.2 

7.6 

12.3 

14.3 

14.2 

14.4 

14.6 

9.9 

12.7 

14.2 

14.1 

14.3 

15.3 

10.8 

12.7 

14.2 

14.1 

14.4 

16.3 

11.3 

13.2 

14.2 

14.0 

14.2 

17.0 

11.9 

13.3 

14.2 

14.0 

14.0 

16.2 

11.5 

13.6 

14.0 

14.2 

13.9 

15.8 

12.1 

13.8 

14.3 

13.9 

13.9 

14.2 

15.1 
15.2 
16.0 
17.1 
18.0 
19.1 
18.0 
18.4 


Service 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  .li^OOO-. 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000-... 
$1,000  to  $5,000.. 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  com- 
piled net  profits 


3.6 

11.1 

14.8 

14.2 

14.6 

13.9 

6.3 

11.6 

14.2 

14.0 

14.3 

14.4 

8.3 

12.2 

13.5 

13.6 

13.9 

14.4 

10.3 

12.6 

13.5 

13.1 

13.7 

14.7 

10.2 

12.4 

13.4 

13.2 

12.9 

15.6 

10.8 

12.6 

13.1 

12.9 

13.0 

15.5 

10.9 

12.7 

13.8 

11.9 

12.2 

15.5 

9.4 

10.3 

10.7 

11.7 

10.4 

15.5 

5.1 

11.8 

13.1 

13.0 

11.2 

15.4 

14.3 

14.7 
15.0 
15.9 
15.7 
15.9 
15.7 
13.9 
13.6 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  tax- 
able net  income 


14.9 
15.5 
16.1 
17.4 
17.4 
18.0 
18.9 
16.9 
15.9 


3.6 

11.2 

15.1 

14.4 

14.7 

13.9 

6.4 

11.9 

14.5 

14.3 

14.7 

14.5 

8.7 

12.9 

14.3 

14.1 

14.4 

14.4 

10.7 

13.0 

14.1 

14.0 

14.4 

14.8 

11.0 

13.3 

14.2 

14.1 

14.2 

15.7 

11.7 

13.5 

14.0 

14.0 

14.2 

15.5 

11.8 

13.9 

14.3 

13.3 

13.8 

15.5 

10.4 

13.5 

13.9 

13.8 

13.9 

15.5 

12.0 

13.6 

14.5 

14.6 

13.7 

15.4 

Construction 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  com- 
piled net  profits 

Under  $50 .  . 

2.4 
6.7 
8.0 
9.4 
9.8 
10.4 
10.5 
7.2 

6.9 
9.1 
10.5 
11.8 
10.4 
10.9 
10.5 
11.0 

14.6 
13.9 
14.6 
14.2 
12.5 
11.9 
9.9 
11.9 
11.5 

14.5 
14.1 
14.2 
13.4 
13.2 
12.8 
11.3 
11.7 

15.1 
15.1 
14.9 
14.3 
13.8 
14.3 
12.7 
12.5 

15.0 
16.2 
15.2 
16.4 
16.1 
15.5 
17.0 
15.3 

15.8 

$50  to  $100 

16.4 

$100  to  $250 

16.3 

$250  to  $500... 

18.7 

$500  to  $1,000-  . 

16.9 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

17.3 

$5,000  to  $10,000-- 

13.8 

$10,000  to  $50,000. - 

Over  $50,000 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


173 


Table  13-A. 


■Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments,  1931-37,  by  size  of  cor- 
porations and  industries — Continued 


Construction— Continued 


Size  classes  based  on  total  assets  (in  thousands) 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936 

1937 

Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  tax- 
able net  income 

Under  $50 

2.4 
5.8 
8.2 
9.9 
10.2 
11.4 
11.7 
10.8 

7.0 
9.3 
11.0 
12.5 
12.1 
13.0 
13.7 
11.7 

14.7 
14.4 
15.6 
15.2 
14.3 
14.7 
13.8 
14.0 

14.7 
14.7 
14.6 
14.5 
14.5 
14.3 
13.7 
13.8 

15.2 
15.4 
14.9 
15.1 
14.7 
16.0 
13.8 
13.8 

15.0 
16.3 
15.3 
16.6 
16.4 
15.8 
17.1 
15.7 

17.0 
17.9 
17.7 
21.1 
19.3 
19.5 
16.4 

$50  to  $100- 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500-.- 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

$5,000  to  $10,000. 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

Over  $50,000 

Public  Utilities 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100- 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000.... 
$1,000  to  $5,000.. 
$5,000  to  $10,000. 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Under  $50 

$50to$100_. 

$100  to  $250. 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1, 000. — 
$1,000  to  $5,000-. 
$5,000  to  $10,000- 
$10,000  to  $50,000 
Over  $50,000 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  com- 
piled net  profits 


3.4 

11.9 

14.6 

14.5 

14.8 

,B.r 

14.1 

6.7 

12.6 

14.3 

14.1 

14.6 

13.9 

15.1 

8.3 

12.6 

14.1 

13.6 

14.3 

14.5 

15.6 

10.3 

12.5 

13.4 

13.6 

13.9 

15.4 

15.5 

11.1 

12.3 

13.6 

13.5 

13.9 

15.2 

16.0 

11.9 

12.6 

13.4 

13.4 

13.4 

15.4 

15.8 

11.2 

12.6 

12.8 

13.2 

13.2 

15.1 

15.6 

10.1 

12.3 

12.6 

13.1 

13.2 

14.8 

15.2 

7.4 

10.2 

10.3 

9.9 

9.9 

11.3 

15.2 

Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  tax- 

able net  income 

3.4 

12.1 

14.7 

14.6 

15.0 

13.7 

6.9 

12.7 

14.5 

14.3 

14.8 

13.9 

8.5 

13.0 

14.4 

14.0 

14.6 

14.5 

10.6 

13.1 

13.9 

13.7 

14.3 

15.  5 

11.5 

13.0 

13.8 

13.8 

14.1 

15.2 

11.6 

13.6 

14.0 

13.8 

14.0 

15.4 

11.9 

13.6 

13.9 

13.8 

13.9 

15.1 

11.6 

13.8 

13.9 

13.8 

13.9 

14.9 

12.0 

14.0 

14.1 

13.8 

13.8 

11.4 

14.9 
16.2 
16.5 
16.4 
16.8 
16.7 
16.6 
15.9 
15.6 


Finance 


Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  com- 
piled net  profits 

Under  $50.. 

2.6 
3.7 
6.3 
6.4 
6.5 
7.2 
7.0 
6.4 
6.0 

11.5 
11.9 
11.2 
10.6 
9.2 
7.8 
6.8 
6.4 
6.2 

12.7 
13.4 
13.0 
11.9 
10.7 
9.8 
7.4 
6.6 
5.2 

13.3 
13.3 
12.5 
11.5 
9.6 
8.5 
7.2 
6.9 
3.1 

13.7 
13.7 
12.7 
10.9 
9.4 
7.6 
7.6 
6.7 
3.1 

11.3 
11.1 
11.1 
10.0 
9.2 
8.4 
7.0 
6.3 
4.0 

11.9 

$50  to  $100       

11.6 

$100  to  $250 

11.0 

$250  to  $500 

9.7 

$500  to  $1,000                                                                      

8.4 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

6.9 

$5,000  to  $10,000                                                       

6.3 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

6.1 

Over  $50,000 

5.2 

Federal  income  taxes  as  percentages  of  com- 
piled net  profits 

Under  $50 

2.8 

3.9 

5.9 

7.7 

8.7 

10.5 

11.1 

11.7 

11.5 

12.0 
12.5 
12.5 
12.3 
12.2 
12.0 
12.6 
12.6 
13.7 

14.2 
14.1 
14.2 
14.0 
14.2 
13.8 
13.5 
13.9 
14.1 

14.3 
14.1 
14.1 
14.1 
14.0 
14.0 
13.7 
13.8 
13.8 

14.6 
14.8 
14.5 
14.5 
14.4 
14.3 
14.2 
14.2 
14.0 

11.3 
11.3 
11.2 
10.5 
10.0 
9.2 
7.6 
6.8 
4.5 

14.3 

$50  to  $100       .  -               

14.0 

$100  to  $250                                                                     

14.5 

$250  to  $500 

15.3 

$500  to  $1,000                                     

16.3 

$1,000  to  $5,000                                                                  --- 

16.9 

$5,000  to  $10  000                                                                          

18.1 

$10,000  to  $50,000                                             - -- 

17.6 

Over  $50,000                                                                  

21.2 

174 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table    14. — Federal   corporate   income-tax   payinents   and    credits   for    investment 
incoine,  hy  size  classes  and  industries,  1936-37 


1936— Normal  tax  as  percent  of— 

1937— Normal  tax  as  percent  of— 

Size  classes  based  on  total 
assets  (in  thousands) 

Compiled 
net  profit 

Profits  less 
85  percent 
of  divi- 
dends 

Taxable 
net  in- 
come! 

Compiled 
net  profit 

Profits  less 
85  percent 
of  divi- 
dends 

Taxable 
net  in- 
come! 

MANUFACTURING 

Under  $50 

11.5 
10.7 
11.6 
12.5 
13.2 
13.6 
13.6 
13.0 
12.4 
11.8 

11.5 
10.8 
11.8 
12.8 
13.5 
14.2 
14.5 
14.6 
14.6 
15.1 

11.6 
10.8 
11.8 
12.8 
13.6 
14.4 
14.7 
14,8 
14.8 
15.3 

9.8 
10.5 
11.4 
12.4 
13.1 
13.7 
13.7 
13.5 
13.4 
12.0 

9.8 
10.6 
11.6 
12.6 
13.4 
14.3 
14.6 
14.7 
14.9 
15.0 

10.0 

$50  to  $100. 

10.8 

$100  to  $250 

11.8 

$250  to  $500 

12.8 

$500  to  $1,000 

13.7 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

14.5 
14.8 

$10,000  to  $50,000.. 

15.0 

$50,000  to  $100,000            

15.0 

Over  $100,000 

15.2 

FOOD 

Under  $50 

9.3 
10.1 
10.9 
12.2 
12.8 
13.5 
13.7 
13.4 
13.2 
12.2 

9.3 
10.2 
11.1 
12.4 
1.3.2 
14.1 
14.7 
14.9 
14.7 
14.9 

9.5 
10.4 
11.2 
12.7 
13.4 
14.4 
14.8 
15.0 
15.0 
15.0 

9.2 
9.9 
11.0 
11.9 
12.6 
13.6 
13.7 
13.6 
13.2 
11.3 

9.3 
10.0 
11.1 
12.1 
13.0 
14.1 
14.8 
14.8 
14.8 
15.8 

9.5 

$50  to  $100 

10.2 

$100  to  $250 

11.2 

$250  to  $500 

12.2 

$500  to  $1,000 

13.2 

$1,000  to  $5,000      

14.4 

$5,000  to  $10,000. 

14.9 

$10,000  to  $50,000 -. 

14.9 

$50,000  to  $100,000-.., 

15.1 

Over  $100,000 

15.9 

BEVERAGES 

Under  $50                 .  . 

11.0 
11.7 
12.5 
13.5 
13.7 
14.3 
13.3 
14.6 
9.4 

11.0 
11.8 
12.8 
13.6 
14.0 
14.6 
14.6 
14.8 
15.0 

11.2 
11.9 
12.9 
13.7 
14.1 
14.7 
14.8 
15.0 
15.0 

11.0 
11.7 
12.8 
13.5 
13.6 
14.2 
14.5 
13.7 
14.0 

11.1 
11.8 
12.9 
13.6 
14.0 
14.4 
14.7 
14.6 
15.0 

11.3 

$50  to  $100 

12.0 

$100  to  $250 .      ... 

13.0 

$250  to  $500 

13.7 

$500  to  $1,000    

14.1 

$1,000  to  !»15.000 

14.6 

$5,000  to  S'.O.OOO 

14.9 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

14.9 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

15.0 

Over  $100,000 

TOBACCO 

Under  $50 .    .. 

10.4 
10.1 
11.0 
11.1 
12.6 
14.0 
13.2 
14.0 
13.9 
13.9 

10.4 
10.1 
11.2 
11.2 
12.8 
14.2 
14.6 
14.7 
14.5 
14.8 

10.4 
10.2 
11.2 
11.6 
12.8 
14.7 
14.7 
14.9 
15.0 
15.0 

9.8 
10.0 
11.1 
10.9 
13.0 
13.9 
13.2 
13.5 
14.6 
14.1 

9.8 
10.0 
11.3 
11.5 
13.0 
14.1 
14.6 
14.6 
14.8 
14.9 

9.8 

$50  to  $100 

10.4 

$100  to  $250     ... 

11.5 

$250  to  $500 

12.3 

$500  to  $1,000    

13.1 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

14.6 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

14.7 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

14.9 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

15.0 

Over  $100,000 

15.0 

TEXTILES 

Under  $50... 

9.2 
9.8 
11.1 
12.1 
12.9 
13.6 
13.3 
14.0 
13.5 

9.2 
9.8 
11.2 
12.3 
13.1 
14.1 
14.5 
14.7 
13.8 

9.4 
10.0 
11.3 
12.4 
13.3 
14.3 
14.7 
14.9 
15.0 

9.5 
9.1 
10.9 
12.0 
12.9 
13.4 
13.7 
14.0 
15.0 
7.6 

9.5 
10.1 
11.0 
12.1 
13.1 
14.0 
14.4 
14.6 
15.0 
12.3 

9.6 

$50  to  $100. 

10.3 

$100  to  $250 

11.2 

$250  to  $500--.            

12.3 

$500  to  $1,000 

13.3 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

14.3 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

14.8 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

14.9 

$50,000  to  $100,000     .. 

16.0 

Over  $100,000 

16.0 

1  "Taxable  net  income"  consists  of  compiled  net  profits  less  the  sum  of  the  following:  (a)  85  percent  of 
dividends  received  from  domestic  corporations  subject  to  tax;  (6)  all  interest  received  on  governmental 
obligations;  and  (c)  the  amount  of  the  excess-profits  tax. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


175 


Table    14. — Federal   corporate   income-tax   paytnents   and    credits   for    investment 
income,  hy  size  classes  and  industries,  1936-37 — Continued 


1936— Normal  tax  as  percent  of- 

1937— Normal  tax  as  percent  of— 

Size  classes  based  on  total 
assets  (in  thousands) 

Compiled 
net  profit 

Profits  less 
85  percent 
of  divi- 
dends 

Taxable 
net  in- 
come 

Compiled 
net  profit 

Profits  less 
85  percent 
of  divi- 
dends 

Taxable 
net  in- 
come 

CLOTHING 

Under  $50 

9.1 
10.2 
11.0 
12.0 
12.6 
13.8 
13.9 
14.2 

9.2 
10.3 
11.1 
12.1 
13.3 
14.2 
14.4 
14.3 

9.2 

10.4 
11.2 
12.2 
13.4 
14.3 
14.8 
14.9 

9.0 
10.0 
11.0 
11.5 
12.9 
13.2 
13.0 
13.6 

9.0 
10.1 
11.1 
11.7 
13.0 
14.1 
14.5 
14.1 

9.1 
10.2 
11.2 
11.8 
13.0 
14.2 
14.5 
14.9 

$50  to  $100 

.$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1.000 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

Over  $100,000 

LEATHER 

Under  $50 

8.9 
10.0 
10.9 
11.6 
12.7 
13.7 
14.4 
12.9 

9.0 
10.0 
11.0 
11.9 
13.2 
14.2 
14.5 
12.9 

9.1 
10.1 
11.1 
12.0 
13.4 
14.4 
14.7 
12.9 

9.0 
10.1 
11.1 
11.6 
12.3 
13.6 
13.7 
11.6 
14.9 

9.1 
10.1 
11.2 
12.2 
13.0 
14.1 
14.4 
14.7 
15.0 

9  2 

$50  to  $100 

10  2 

$100  to  $250 

11  4 

$250  to  $500 

12  4 

$500  to  $1,000 

13  1 

$1,000  to  $5,000      

14  3 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

14  7 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

14.8 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

15  Q 

Over  $100,000 

RUBBER 

Under  $50    

9.6 
10.0 

11.6 
12.7 
13.1 
13.7 
13.9 
13.8 
15.0 
10.9 

9.6 
10.0 
11.8 
12.8 
13.6 
14.1 
14.6 
14.8 
15.0 
14.9 

9.7 
10.1 
11.9 
13.0 
13.7 
14.4 
14.8 
14.8 
15.0 
14.9 

9.7 
10.4 
11.3 
12.7 
13.1 
14.1 
14.0 
13.1 
15.0 

4.1 

9.7 
10.6 
11.5 
12.7 
13.1 
14.3 
14.6 
14.8 
15.0 
15.0 

10.0 

$50  to  $100 

10.7 

$100  to  $250 

11.5 

$250  to  $500 

12.9 

$500  to  $1,000 

13.1 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

14.5 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

14.7 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

14.8 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

15.0 

Over  $100,000 

15.0 

FOREST  PRODUCTS 

Under  $60 

9.2 
10.0 
10.9 
11.5 
12.5 
13.2 
13.7 
10.5 
12.0 
11.5 

9.3 
10.1 
11.0 
11.9 
13.1 
14.0 
14.4 
14.9 
14.7 
14.8 

9.7 
10.3 
11.3 
12.6 
14.0 
14.2 
14.7 
14.9 
15.0 
15.0 

9.2 
10.0 
11.0 
11.9 
12.5 
12.9 
13.1 
12.2 

6.5 
13.0 

9.3 
10.1 
11.0 
12.1 
12.9 
13.9 
14.4 
14.7 
13.6 
14.9 

9.5 

$50  to  $100 

10.4 

$100  to  $250 

11.2 

$250  to  $500 

12.4 

$500  to  $1,000. 

13.2 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

14.1 

$5,000  to  $10,000.. 

14.6 

$10,000  to  $50,000--. 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

14.8 
14.9 

Over  $100,000 

15.0 

PAPER 

Under  $50 

9.0 
10.4 
11.4 
12.2 
13.0 
13.5 
14.0 
13.6 

9.4 
10.5 
11.6 
12.6 
13.4 
14.2 
14.5 
14.1 

9.7 
10.9 
11.9 
13.2 
14.0 
14.4 
14.8 
15.0 

9.5 
9.9 
11.2 
12.5 
12.8 
13.5 
13.9 
13.4 
14.3 
9.9 

9.5 
10.0 
11.4 
12.8 
13.2 
14.2 
14.5 
14.7 
15.0 
14.5 

9.7 

$50  to  $100        -            ... 

10.0 

$100  to  $250 

11.6 

$250  to  $500. 

12.9 

$500  to  $1,000 

13.4 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

14.4 

$5,000  to  $10,000    .     

14.8 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

14.9 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

15.0 

Over  $100,000     . 

9.8 

14.9 

i4.9 

15.0 

176 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table    14. — Federal   corporate   income-tax   'payments   and   credits   for    ijivestment 
income,  by  size  classes  and  industries,  1936-37 — Continued 


Size  classes  based  on  total 
assets  (in  thousands) 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 .- 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000... . 
$5,000  to  $10,000... 
$10,000  to  $50,000.. 
$50,000  to  $100,000- 
Over  $100,000 


Under  $50. ., 

$50  to  $100- , 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 - 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000.-.. 
$5,000  to  $10,000--, 
$10,000  to  $50,000. 
$50,000  to  $100,000 
Over  $100,000 


Under  $50- 

$50  to  $100 , 

$100  to  $250 , 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000—, 
$5,000  to  $10,000.-. 
$10,000  to  $50,000., 
$50,000  to  $100,000, 
Over  $100,000 


Under  $50. 

$50  to  $100. 

$100  to  $250. 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000-- 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

$10,000  to  $50,000.-.. 
$50,000  to  $100,000... 
Over  $100,000 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100. 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1.000 

$1,000  to  $5,000... 
$5,000  to  $10.000.. 
$10,000  to  $50,000. 
$50,000  to  $100,000 
Over  $100,000 


1936— Normal  tax  as  percent  of— 


Compiled 
net  profit 


Profits  less 
85  percent 
of  divi- 
dends 


Taxable 
net  in- 
come 


1937— Normal  tax  as  percent  of- 


Compiled 
net  profit 


Profits  less 
85  percent 
of  divi- 
dends 


Taxable 
net  in- 
come 


10.0 
10.3 
11.1 
12.0 
12.8 
13.3 
13.3 
10.3 
11.3 


10.7 
11.7 
12.6 
13.6 
13.3 
13.0 
12.8 
12.1 
9.7 


10.5 
12.1 
12.8 
13.7 
13.9 
14.2 
10.3 
10.7 
8.0 


9.3 
10.2 
11.6 
12.2 
13.0 
13.5 
13.3 
12.7 
13.4 
13.7 


9.3 
10.5 
11.6 
12.6 
13.4 
13.8 
13.9 
13.4 
12.9 
12.6 


10.1 
10.4 
11.4 
12.7 
13.3 
14.2 
14.4 
13.1 
14.6 


10.3 
10.6 
12.0 
13.8 
14.1 
14.4 
14.8 
13.4 
15.0 


9.5 

10.1 

11.2 

12.1 

12.8 

13.2 

12.9 

11.7 

11.5 

4.3 

11.0 
11.8 
12.8 
13.8 
14.3 
14.6 
14.6 
15.0 
15.0 


10.0 
11.2 
12.0 
13.0 
14.0 
14.6 
14.9 
15.0 
16.0 
15.0 


9.8 

10.6 

11.6 

12.7 

13.4 

13.4 

13.3 

13.1 

12.7 

10.2 

PETROLEUM 


9.6 

10.  5 

12.2 

13.1 

13.9 

15.0 

14.9 

14.7 

15.0 

14.8 

10.6 
12.4 
13.1 
14.0 
15.0 
14.9 
14.8 
15.0 
15.0 


9.1 

11.1 

12.6 

12.6 

13.9 

13.1 

13.7 

13.9 

11.3 

9.1 

STONE,  CLAY,  AND  GLASS 


10. 

11. 

12. 

13. 

14. 

14. 

14. 

15.0 

14.7 


9.6 
10.6 
11.9 
12.7 
13.5 
14.4 
14.8 
14.9 
15.0 
15.0 


10.2 
11.4 
12.2 
13.2 
13.7 
13.6 
13.5 
13.7 
13.4 


9.4 
10.6 
11.7 
12.8 
13.5 
13.9 
14.6 
14.7 
14.7 
14.8 


9.6 

10.8 

11.9 

13.0 

13.8 

14.1 

14.9 

15.0 

15.0 

15.0 

10.1 

10.6 

11.5 

12.6 

13.3 

13.9 

13.9 

13.7 

14.1 

13.1 

9.6 

10.2 

11.6 

12.4 

13.4 

14.1 

14.3 

14.6 

14.2 

14.9 

9.8 
10.7 
11.8 
12.9 
13.8 
14.4 
14.6 
14.8 
15.0 
14.9 


9.1 
11.1 
12.6 
13.1 
14.0 
14.6 
14.5 
14.9 
14.6 
15.8 


9.2 
10.2 
11.6 
12.4 
13.4 
14.2 
14.5 
14.7 
14.9 
14.8 


10.2 
10.6 
11.6 
12.8 
13.5 
14.3 
14.6 
14.6 
15.0 
14.8 


10.4 
11.6 
12.6 
13.6 
14.4 
14.8 
14.9 
15.0 
14.9 


10.9 
12.0 
13.0 
14.0 
14.6 
14.9 
15.1 
15.0 
15.0 


9.2 
11.5 
12.8 
13.3 
14.1 
14.8 
14.8 
14.9 
14.9 
15.9 


9.5 
10.4 
11.7 
12.7 
13.7 
14.4 
14.7 
14.9 
15.0 
15.0 


10.4 
10.9 
11.9 
13.0 
13.8 
14.6 
14.9 
14.9 
15.1 
15.0 


CONCEXTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


177 


Table    14. — Federal   corporate   incoine-tax   -payments   and    credits   for    investment 
income,  by  size  classes  and  industries,  1936-37 — Continued 


1936— Normal  tax  as  percent  of— 

1937— Normal  tax  as  percent  of— 

Size  classes  based  on  total 
assets  (in  thousands) 

Compiled 
net  profit 

Profits  less 
85  percent 
of  divi- 
dends 

Taxable 
net  in- 
come 

Compiled 
net  profit 

Profits  less 
85  percent 
of  divi- 
dends 

Taxable 
net  in- 
come 

MOTOR  VEHICLES 

Under  $50 

9.2 
10.  5 
11.7 
12.6 
13.9 
U.4 
14.0 
14.0 
13.6 
13.7 

9.4 
10.  G 
12.1 
12.8 
14.1 
14.6 
14.5 
14.9 
14.9 
14.9 

9.7 
10.8 
12.2 
12.9 
14.2 
14.7 
14.9 
14.9 
15.0 
15.0 

10.0 
11.5 
11.8 
13.2 
13.8 
14.2 
14.2 
14.4 
11.9 
13.4 

10.0 
11.5 
12.0 
13.2 
14.0 
14.6 
14.4 
14.8 
14.2 
14.9 

10.2 
11.7 
12.3 
13.4 
14.1 
14.7 
14.9 
15.0 
15.0 
15.0 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250        -.     - 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

Over  $100,000      

MINING 

Under  $50 

10.3 
10.5 
11.5 
12.0 
12.2 
12.7 
12.3 
12.4 
12.9 
7.9 

10.3 
11.0 
12.0 
12.8 
13.3 
14.3 
14.4 
14.7 
14.2 
14.8 

10.5 
11.1 
12.1 
12.9 
13.5 
14.6 
14.8 
15.0 
15.2 
15.0 

10.4 
10.8 
11.4 
12.5 
12.5 
12.8 
12.0 
12.8 
13.1 
9.8 

10.4 
11.0 
11.7 
12.9 
13.4 
14.3 
14.3 
14.4 
14.4 
14.8 

10  6 

$50  to  $100 

11  2 

$100  to  $250 

11  9 

$250to$500. 

$500  to  $1,000 

13.1 
13  6 

$1,000  to  $5,000 - 

14  6 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

14  8 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

15  0 

$50,000  to  $100,000     . 

15  0 

Over  $100,000 

15  0 

TRADE 

Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

9.1 
10.0 
10.9 
11.7 
12.5 
13.3 
13.7 
13.5 
11.6 
14.1 

9.2 
10.1 
11.1 
12.0 
13.2 
14.0 
14.6 
14.8 
14.9 
14.7 

9.3 
10.3 
11.2 
12.2 
13.2 
14.2 
14.8 
15.0 
15.0 
15.0 

9.1 
10.0 
10.8 
11.7 
12.5 
13.4 
13.6 
13.5 
12.8 
12.6 

9.2 
10.1 
11.0 
12.1 
13.0 
14.0 
14.5 
14.7 
15.0 
14.9 

9.3 
10  2 

$100  to  $250 

11. 1 

$250  to  $500 

12  3 

$500  to  $1,000 

13.2 

$1,000  to  $5,000      .-- 

14.3 

$5,000  to  $10,000 ..... 

14.8 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

.$50,000  to  $100,000 

14.9 
15.1 

Over  $100,000     

15.0 

SERVICE 

Under  .$50 

10.1 
10.9 
11.0 
11.6 
12.1 
12.4 
11.6 
12.6 
12.4 

10.2 
11.1 
11.6 
12.6 
13.2 
14.1 
14.5 
14.8 
15.0 

10.3 
11.2 
11.7 
12.7 
13.4 
14.3 
14.6 
14.9 
15.0 

10.2 
10.7 
11.2 
11.6 
12.0 
12.7 
12.3 
12.0 
12.8 

10.2 
10.9 
11.6 
12.4 
13.0 
14.1 
14.8 
14.7 
15.0 

10.4 

$50  to  $100... 

11.1 

$100  to  $250       .  - 

11.8 

$250to$500 

12.6 

$500  to  $1,000      

13.2 

$1,000  to  $5,000 

14.3 

$5,000  to  $10,000.. 

16.0 

$10,000  to  $50,000 

14.7 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

15.0 

Over  $100.000 

' 

CONSTRUCTION 

Under  $50 

9.3 
10.4 
10.7 
12.1 
11.9 
13.0 
13.7 
13.9 

9.4 
10.6 
11.3 
12.8 
14.0 
14.1 
14.6 
14.0 

9.6 
10.9 
11.6 
13.1 
14.7 
14.6 
14.9 
14.9 

9.4 
10.2 
11.1 
11.9 
11.9 
13.1 
12.4 
13.7 
12.7 

9.6 
10.3 
11.4 
12.5 
12.8 
14.1 
14.3 
14.2 
14.2 

9.8 

$50  to  $100 

10.7 

$100  to  $250 

11.7 

$250  to  $500 

13.0 

$500  to  $1.000 

13.4 

$1,000  to  $5,000- 

14.5 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

14.7 

$10,000  to  $50,000 - 

14.8 

$50,000  to  $100,000 

14.6 

Over  $100,000                              i 

178 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  14. — Federal  corporate  income-tax   payments   and  credits  for  investments 
income,  by  size  classes  and  industries,  1936-37 — Continued 


Size  classes  based  on  total 
assets  (in  thousands) 


1936— Normal  tax  as  percent  of- 


Compiled 
net  proflt 


Profits  less 

85  percent 

of  divi- 

dends 


Taxable 
net  in- 
come 


1937— Normal  tax  as  percent  of— 


Compiled 
net  profit 


Profits  less 
85  percent 
of  divi- 
dends 


Taxable 
net  in- 
come 


PUBLIC  UTIUTIES 


Under  $50_ 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 -.-. 

$250  to  $500 

$500  to  $1.000 

$1,000  to  $5.000 

$5,000  to  $10,000 

$10,000  to  $50,000.... 
$50,000  to  $100,000... 
Over  $100,000 


Under  $50 

$50  to  $100 

$100  to  $250 

$250  to  $500. 

$500  to  $1,000 

$1,000  to  $5,000 ... 
$5,000  to  $10.000.. 
$10,000  to  $50,000. 
$50,000  to  $100,000 
Over  $100,000 


9.4 
10.8 
11.8 
12.2 
13.0 
13.8 
14.1 
14.2 
14.4 
10.2 


9.5 

10.9 

11.9 

12.5 

13.3 

14.4 

14.5 

14.7 

1,5.0 

15.0 

9.6 

11.1 

12.1 

12.6 

13.4 

14.5 

14.6 

14.9 

15.0 

15.4 

9.5 

10.7 

11.7 

12.1 

13.1 

13.7 

14.0 

14.3 

14.6 

10.5 

8.5 
8.4 
8.6 
8.0 
7.3 
6.5 
5.4 
5.2 
4.4 
3.0 


10.3 
10.3 
11.0 
10.9 
10.7 
10.9 
10.9 
10.5 
10.6 
7.9 


10.5  i 

10.6  I 

11.7  I 
12.9  I 
14.0  I 
15.0 
15.0 
14.9 
14.6 
15.0 


8.8 
8.4 
8.7 
8.0 
7.0 
5.7 
5.3 
5.2 
4.7 
3.5 


9.6 
10.9 
11.9 
12.4 
13.3 
14.1 
14.5 
14.7 
14.9 
14.9 


10.5 
10.2 
11.0 
10.9 
10.6 
10.3 
11.0 
11.0 
12.6 


9.7 
11.1 
12.1 
12.6 
1.3.4 
14.2 
14.7 
14.9 
14.9 
15.1 


10.8 
10.5 
11.7 
13.1 
14.3 
15.5 
16.7 
16.4 
18.8 
20.7 


Source:  Computed  from  the  Sourcebook  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue. 

Table  15. — Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments  and  credits  for  investment  income^ 

by  minor  industries,  1937 


M.\nufacturing: 

Food 

Baking  and  confection- 
ery products..- 

Canned  products 

Mill  products 

Packing-house  products 

Sugar 

Other  food  products. -. 

Beverages 

Nonalcoholic 

Alcoholic 

To  bacco 

Textiles 

Cotton 

Woolen  and  worsted... 

Silk  and  rayon 

Carpets 

Other  textiles 

Clothing  and  apparel. ., 
Knit  goods 

Leather 

Shoes 

Other  leather  products. 


Normal  tax  as  a  per- 
centage of— 


Profits  i 

Corpo-      less     j  Taxable 

rate       credit  |     net 

profits  for  divi-  income 

i  dends  1 


12.1 

13.6 
13.5 
12.8 
9.6 
12.5 
12.5 
13.8 
13.5 
14.0 
14.0 
13.0 
13.5 
12.3  I 
12.5 
14.1  I 
13.1  I 

12.3  i 
12.9  i 
13.1  I 

13.4  ' 
12.4  i 


14.3 


14.4 


14.1 

14.3 

14.1 

14.2 

13.6 

14.0 

16.0 

16.1 

14.9 

15.0 

14.0 

14.2 

14  3 

14.4 

14.0 

14.2 

14.4 

14.6 

14.8 

14.9 

13.7 

14.1 

13.9 

14.2 

13.4 

13.7 

13.9 

14.7 

14.2 

14.5 

13.7 

14.0 

12.7 

12.9 

1.3.  3 

13.5 

13.7 

13.8 

14.0 

14.1 

12.9 

13.1 

Surtax  on  un- 
distributed 
profits  as  a  per- 
centage of— 


Corpo- 
rate 
profits 


Taxable 

net 
income 


1.3 

1.6 
1.7 
1.7 


1.2 
3.5 
2.4 
4.2 

.7 


2.5 
3.4 
4.3 
1.6 
2.3 
L7 
2.8 
3.2 
1.8 
1.3 
3.0 


1.5 

1.6 
2.0 
2.0 
1.0 

.4 
1.4 
4.1 
2.8 
5.0 

.8 
2.9 
4.0 
5.0 
1.9 
2.8 
2.0 
3.2 
3.6 
2.0 
1.4 
3.4 


Excess-profits 
tax  as  a  per- 
centage of— 


Corpo- 
rate 
profits 


0.3 

.3 
.3 
.3 
.3 
.1 
.2 
.6 
.7 
.5 
.1 
.5 
1.0 
.4 
.3 
.3 
.4 
.3 
.3 
.2 
.2 
.4 


Ta.xable 

net 
income 


0.3 

.3 
.4 
.3 
.3 
.2 
.3 
.6 
.7 
.5 
.1 
.6 
1.0 
.5 
.4 
.3 
.4 
.4 
.4 
.3 
.2 
.5 


Total 
tax  as  a 
percent- 
age of 
corpo- 
rate 
profits 


Cash 
divi- 
dends 
paid 
out  as  a 
percent- 
age of 
corpo- 
rate 
profits 


14.2 

15.5 
15.6 
14.8 
10.7 
13.0 
14.0 
17.8 
16.6 
18.7 
14.7 
16.1 
17.9 
17.1 
14.4 
16.7 
15.2 
15.5 
16.4 
15.1 
14.8 
15.9 


84.9 

78.3 
67.5 
79.4 
106.4 
98.3 


68.0 
55.3 
85.7 
74.2 
64.2 
78.2 
88.1 
91.2 
74.4 
66.9 
66.7 
85.9 
86.6 
76.0 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


179 


Table  15. — Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments  and  credits  for  investrneni  income 
by  minor  industries,  1937 — Continued 


Manufacturing— Con. 


Rubber 

Tires  and  tubes 

Bone,  celluloid,  and 

ivory  products 

Other  rubber 

Forest  products 

Sawmill   and    planing- 

mill  products 

Furniture    and    other 

wood  products... 

Paper 

Printing  and  publishing.. 

Chemicals 

Chemicals  proper 

Petroleum 

Fertilizers 

Paints 

Other  chemicals 

Stone,  clay,  and  glass 

Metals 

Iron  and  steel 

Motor  vehicles 

Railroad  equipment 

•   Machinery: 

Factory 

Agricultural.-. 

Electrical.. 

Household 

Miscellaneous. 

Office  equipment 

Metal    building    mate- 
rials ,  supplies 

Hardw^are  and  tools 

Precious  metals . 

Other  metal  products... 
Miscellaneous     manufac- 
turing   

Radios 

Airplanes 

Instruments,  etc 

Total  manufacturing 


Mining - 


Metal 

Anthracite  coal 

Bituminous,  lignite, 

and  peat 

Oil  and  gas 

Other  minerals 

N.  E.   C,  lessees  and 

holders.. 


Trade. 


Wholesale 

Retail 

Wholesale  and  retail. 

Commission 

Other  trade 


Service. 


Normal  tax  as  a  per- 
centage of — 


Corpo- 
rate 
profits 


Domestic 

Amusements. 

Theaters 

Motion-picture  pro- 
ducers  

Motion-picture  the- 
aters  

Other  amusements- 

Less  than  0.05  of  1  percent. 


10.8 

8.7 

14.1 
13.4 

12.2 

12.4 

12.5 
13.2 
11.9 
12.3 
11.8 
10.0 
11.9 
12.8 
12.6 
13.3 
13.4 
13.2 
13.5 
13.4 

13.2 
13.4 
13.3 
13.1 
13.7 
14.1 

13.1 
13.  7 
13.5 
13.4 

13.3 
13.8 
13.3 
13.3 
12.9 

11.9 

11.7 
11.5 

11.6 
11.6 
13.1 

12.6 

12.4 

12.3 
12.9 
11.8 
11.2 
11.6 

11.6 

11.2 
11.5 
10.9 


11.6 
13.0 


Profits 

less 

credit 

for  divi 

dends 


14.3 
14.8 

14.2 
13.9 
13.2 

13.5 

12.8 
14.7 
13.6 
14.4 
14.8 
15.3 
13.5 
14.1 
14.2 
14.2 
14.3 
14.4 
14.8 
14.7 

13.9 
14.6 
14.6 
13.9 
14.1 
14.6 

14.0 
14.0 
13.9 
14.4 

14.2 
14.3 
15.0 
14.1 
14.4 

14.1 

14.5 
11.9 

13.4 
14.0 
13.8 

13.6 

13.4 

13.3 
13.5 
13.1 
13.2 
13.6 

12.8 

11.8 
13.4 
12.8 

15.3 

1.3.1 
13:2 


Taxable 

net 
income 


14.5 
14.9 

14.5 
14.1 
13.4 

13.7 

13.1 
14.9 
13.9 
14.6 
14.8 
15.5 
13.7 
14.3 
14.5 
14.5 
14.5 
14.6 
14.9 
15.1 

14.3 
14.8 
14.8 
14.5 
14.4 
14.8 

14.3 
14.4 
14.2 
14.5 

14.4 
14.4 
15.3 
14.3 
14.6 

14.5 

14.7 
13.9 

13.9 
14.4 
14.0 

14.0 

13.5 

13.5 
13.7 
13.4 
13.5 
13.7 

13.0 

12.0 
13.5 
12.9 

15.4 

13.2 
13.4 


Surtax  on  un- 
distributed 
profits  as  a  per- 
centage of— 


Corpo- 
rate 
profits 


2.3 
1.5 

2.0 
3.6 
2.2 

1.2 

3.5 
2.9 
2.6 
1.4 
1.2 
1.3 
2.5 
2.3 
1.4 
1.8 
3.0 
2.6 
2.0 
2.5 

3.0 
4.9 
1.7 
2.2 
4.0 
3.0 

2.6 
4.0 
3.1 
2.2 

3.1 
3.5 
4.3 
2.9 
2.3 

1.2 

1.1 
1.3 

2.3 
1.3 
1.4 


3.0 
2.7 
2.5 
3.1 
1.0 


3.2 
2.3 
1.8 


2.0 
4.0 


Taxable 

net 
income 


2.5 
1.6 

2.3 

4.1 
2.5 

1.3 

4.0 

3.4 

3.0 

1.7 

.1 

1.4 

.8 

.3 

.3 

1.9 

3.5 

2.8 

2.2 

2.8 

.3.2 
5.3 
1.8 
2.3 
4.1 
3.5 

3.1 
4.8 
3.7 
2.6 

3.6 
4.1 
5.0 
3.4 
2.7 

1.5 

1.3 
1.7 

2.7 
1.5 
1.6 

1.1 

3.2 

3.4 
3.2 
2.9 
3.5 
1.1 


3.7 
2.6 
2.1 


2.3 
4.7 


Excess-profits 
tax  as  a  per- 
centage of— 


Corpo-  Taxable 

rate         net 
profits    income 


0.2 

(0 


1.1 

.5 
.3 
.2 
1.2 
.2 
2.5 
2.2 
1.4 
.5 


.1 
.9 

1.0 


.4 

.7 
.6 
.5 

1.0 

1.2 
.1 

.4 
.6 
.5 

2.1 

.6 


.5 
1.2 


0.3 
.1 

.5 
.5 
1.0 


1.3 
.5 
.4 
.3 
1.2 
.4 
2.8 
2.5 
1.6 
.6 
1.0 
1.0 
.1 
1.1 

1.0 
1.0 
.3 
.2 
1.9 
.5 

1.1 
1.6 
1.2 

.7 

.7 
.4 


1.2 


1.5 
.2 


2.3 

.7 


1.0 

.4 


1.2 


Total 
tax  as  a 
percent- 
age of 
corpo- 
rate 
profits 


Cash 
divi- 
dends 
paid 
out  as  a 
percent- 
age of 
corpo- 
rate 
profits 


13.4 
10.2 

16.6 
17.5 
15.4 

14.4 

16.6 
16.7 
14.8 
13.9 
13.2 
11.5 
15.2 
15.4 
14.3 
15.7 
17.3 
16.8 
15.7 
16.6 

17.3 
19.2 
15.3 
15.5 
19.4 
17.6 

16.8 
19.2 
17.7 
16.3 

17.0 
17.7 
18.4 
16.8 
15.7 

14.1 

14.1 
12.8 

14.3 
13.4 
14.9 

15.7 

15.8 

16.2 
16.0 
15.2 
14.9 
12.9 

15.1 


90.2 
112.5 


68.1 
61.6 


76.1 

62.1 
64.9 
67.0 
75.1 
75.1 
90.7 
74.4 
74.3 
75.1 
71.2 
61.9 
64.3 
66.3 
71.9 

61.3 
44.2 
7.3.2 
66.1 
5.3.6 
59.7 

63.2 
55.0 
57.7 
69.1 

63.0 
66.9 
48.4 
64.3 
70.1 

86.1 

82.5 
101.6 

76.8 
94.1 

82.8 

88.7 

65.8 

65.1 
65.4 
66.1 
64.7 
83.9 

64.8 


15.0 
14.4 
13.4 

63.2 
65.2 
73.9 

11.1 

54.8 

14.2 
18.2 

71.0 
52.2 

180 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  15. — Federal  corporate  income-tax  payments  and  credits  for  investment  income^ 
by  minor  industries,  1937 — Continued 


Normal  tax  as 
centage  of- 

aper- 

Surtax  on  un- 
distributed 
profits  as  a  per- 
centage of— 

Excess-profits 
tax  as  a  per- 
centage of— 

Total 
tax  as  a 
percent- 
age of 
corpo- 
rate 
profits 

Cash 
divi- 
dends 
paid 
out  as  a 
percent- 
age of 
corpo- 
rate 
profits 

Corpo- 

rate 

profits 

Profits 

less 
credit 
for  divi- 
dends 

Taxable 

net 
income 

Corpo- 
rate 
profits 

Taxable 

net 
income 

Corpo- 
rate 
profits 

Taxable 

net 
income 

•Service— Continued. 

Professional-. 

Business 

11.6 
12.3 
12.0 

12.1 

11.4 

12.1 
13.7 

12.2 

12.6 
12.2 
14.0 

13.0 
13.4 
12.6 
11.8 

13.7 
13.2 

8.7 
13.8 
13.1 
14.8 
14.1 

4.8 

4.8 
2.8 

3.8 

11.3 
12.1 

3.0 

7.4 
9.6 
9.0 
4.9 
9.2 

12.2 
13.4 
13.1 

12.8 

11.7 

13.0 
14.1 

14.6 

14.3 

14.8 
14.7 

13.9 
13.7 
13.7 
12.3 

14.8 
14.6 

14.7 
14.0 
13.2 
14.8 
14.2 

10.7 

5.3 
2.9 

4.1 

11.3 
14.1 

16.5 

12.4 
11.7 
12.2 
5.3 
12.5 

12.6 
13.6 
13.4 

13.2 

12.2 

13.4 
14.4 

14.7 

14.5 
15.1 
14.9 

14.2 
14.2 
13.8 
12.5 

14.9 
14.7 

14.9 
14.2 
13.3 
14.9 
14.3 

16.5 

18.7 
54.3 

31.7 

14.6 
14.5 

17.6 

14.9 
12.1 
15.2 
22.2 
15.1 

3.4 
2.9 
2.1 

3.4 

4.2 

3.3 
2.1 

.7 

1.3 
1.1 
.8 

2.3 
1.1 
1.9 
2.2 

.4 
1.3 

.1 
2.0 
1.0 
.7 
.8 

1.1 

.6 

4.0 
3.3 
2.5 

4.0 

4.9 

3.9 
2.5 

.8 

1.6 
1.3 
1.0 

2.7 
1.3 
2.2 
2.5 

.5 
1.5 

.1 

2.3 

1.1 

.8 

.9 

1.4 

2.1 

1.6 
.8 
.6 

1.6 

2.3 

1.5 
1.0 

.2 

.4 
.1 
.1 

1.0 

2.4 

.3 

.9 

.3 
.2 

(')  _ 

'.2 
.3 
.3 

.1 

.3 
.1 

.2 

1.7 

.9 

.  7 

1.8 

2.4 

1.7 
1.0 

.3 

.4 
.1 
.1 

1.1 

2.5 

.4 

1.0 

.3 

.2 

0) 

.7 
.2 
.3 
.3 

.3 

.4 
2.0 

3.0 

16.6 
16.0 
14.7 

17.1 

17.9 

17.0 
16.8 

13.1 

14.4 
13.4 
14.9 

16.3 
16.8 
14.8 
14.9 

14.4 
14.7 

8.8 
16.5 
14.3 
15.7 
15.1 

6.0 

5.7 
2.9 

4.0 

11.3 
14.4 

4.3 

11.6 
12.5 
9.0 
4.9 
9.2 

62.7 
65.4 

Other  service ... 

69.8 

Construction 

60.0 

Above  ground ... 

49.6 

Underground    and    on 
surface 

64.5 

Shipbuilding.. 

Public  utilities 

Transportation 

56.4 
88.1 
79.4 

Steam  railroads 

Electric  railroads. . . 
Water    transporta- 
tion 

84.5 
81.5 

67,4 

Air 

84.1 

Autobus 

73.8 

Cartage  and  storage. 
Other  public  utilities: 
Electric  light    and 
power  - 

71.5 
94.1 

Gas 

86.2 

Telephone  and  tele- 
graph  

Radiobroadcasting.. 
Water.  .. 

94.9 
65.7 
83.4 

Pipelines. 

78.2 

Terminals     .. 

88.5 

Finance 

75.2 

Banking 

54.0 

National  banks 

47.9 

State   and   private 
banks 

45.9 

Joint-stock    land 
banks . 

589.6 

Loan  companies 

Investment   trusts, 
etc.. 

2.0 

1.3 

3.8 
2.3 

0) 

2.3 

1.3 

4.6 
2.6 

.4 

.1 

.3 
.6 

,4 

.3 

.6 
.8 
0) 

74.5 
89.1 

Stock     and     bond 
brokers  .. 

68.8 

Real  estate 

74.3 

Insurance . 

33.9 

Life 

49.1 

Other 

0) 

(0 

0) 

0) 

33.4 

Grand  total 

10.7 

13.7 

14.6 

1.8 

2.1 

.4 

.6 

13.0 

74.2 

1  Less  than  0.05  of  1  percent. 

Source:  Computed  from  the  Source  book  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


181 


Table  16. — Federal  taxes  and  corproate  income  paid  out  as  cash  dividends  or  avail- 
able for  reinvestment  or  industrial  replacement  by  small,  medium-sized,  large,  and 
giant  corporations,  1931-37 

[In  millions  of  dollars] 

PART  I 

Small  Corporations  (Assets  Under  $50,000) 


1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936 

1937 

Corporate  profits  before  taxes 

378 

174 

278 

433 

514 

699 

641 

Federal  normal  tax..  ..    .  . 

21 

20 

37 

58 
2 

69 
4 

73 
6 
18 

66 
9 

Excess-profits  tax . 

Undistributed  profits  tax .      .  ..  ._ 

18 

Total  Federal  taxes 

21 

20 

39 

60 

73 

97 

93 

Corporate  profits  after  taxes    . 

357 
191 
378 

544 

154 
102 
94 

148 

239 

88 
127 

278 

373 
212 
172 

333 

441 
216 

188 

413 

602 
436 
223 

389 

548 

Cash  dividends  paid  out 

401 
226 

373 

Income  available  for  reinvestment  and  re- 

Medium-Sized  Corporations  (Assets  from  $250,000  to  $5,000,000) 


Corporate  profits  before  taxes 

931 

537 

891 

1,367 

1,736 

2,415 

2,286 

Federal  normal  tax 

88 

61 

113 
3 

171 
3 

212 
10 

287 
10 
58 

272 

Excess-profits  tax     ..     . 

63 

Undistributed  profits  tax 

17 

Total  Federal  taxes 

88 

61 

116 

174 

222 

355 

352 

Corporate  profits  after  taxes 

843 
635 
365 

573 

476 
363 
234 

347 

775 
373 
328 

730 

1,193 
820 
467 

840 

1,  514 

1,024 

509 

999 

2,060 

1,537 

605 

1,128 

1,934 

Cash  dividends  paid  out 

1,500 

Depreciation  and  depletion 

642 

Income  available  for  reinvestment  and  re- 
placement 

1,076 

Large  Corporations  (Assets  from  $5,000,000  to  $50,000,000) 


1,028 

629 

941 

1,462 

1,859 

2,524 

2,518 

Federal  normal  tax ..     .     . 

96 

69 

110 

1 

167 

1 

.0. 

285 
3? 

294 

44 

Undistributed  profits  tax 

10 

Total  Federal  taxes 

96 

69 

111 

168 

210 

325 

348 

.    932 
821 
355 

466 

560 
509 
260 

311 

830 
606 
353 

577 

1,294 

1,156 

535 

673 

1,669 

1,463 

570 

776 

2,199 

1,814 

665 

1,050 

2,170 

Cash  dividends  paid  out 

1,796 

Depreciation  and  depletion 

Income  available  for  reinvestment  and  re- 
placement   ..  -      .  -     ... - 

708 
1,082 

Giants  (Assets  over  $50,000,000) 


Corporate  profits  before  taxes 

2,305 

1,358 

1,409 

2,051 

2,606 

3,709 

4,126 

187 

132 

150 

1 

183 

212 
6 

338 

1 

28 

400 

Excess-profits  tax 

47 

Undistributed  profits  tax 

5 

Total  Federal  taxes 

187 

132 

151 

183 

218 

367 

452 

Corporate  profits  after  taxes 

2,118 

2,197 

891 

802 

1,226 

1,335 

691 

572 

1,258 

1,289 

803 

772 

1,868 

1,608 

677 

937 

2,388 
1,915 

777 

1,250 

3,342 
3,180 
1,065 

1,227 

3.674 

Cash  dividends  paid  out 

3,397 

1,234 

Income  available  for  reinvestment  and  re- 
placement   

1,511 

262698— 41— No.  9- 


-13 


182 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  16. — Federal  taxes  and  corporate  income  paid  out  as  cash  dividends  or  avail- 
able for  reinvestment  or  industrial  replacement  hy  small,  medium-sized,  large,  and 
giant  corporations,  1931-37 — Continued 

[In  millions  of  dollars] 
PART  II 
[1932=100] 


Corpo- 
rate 
profits 
before 
taxes 

Corporate  profits 
after  taxes 

Cash 
divi- 
dends 
paid 
out 

Depre- 
ciation 
and  de- 
pletion 

Income 
avail- 
able for 

Exclud- 
ing un- 
distrib- 
uted 

Includ- 
ing 

profits 
tax 

reinvest- 
ment 
and  re- 
place- 
ment 

Small  corporations: 
1931 

217 
100 
160 
249 
295 
402 
368 

173 
100 
166 
255 
323 
450 
426 

163 
100 
150 
232 
296 
401 
400 

170 
100 
104 
151 
192 
273 
304 

232 
100 
155 
242 
286 
403 
368 

177 
100 
162 
251 
318 
445 
410 

166 
100 
148 
231 
298 
399 
389 

173 
100 
103 
152 
195 
275 
300 

187 
100 
86 
208 
212 
432 
393 

175 
100 
103 
226 
283 
423 
413 

161 
100 
119 
227 
287 
356 
353 

165 
100 
97 
120 
143 
238 
254 

402 
100 
135 
183 
200 
237 
241 

156 
100 
140 
200 
218 
259 
274 

137 
100 
136 
206 
219 
256 
272 

129 
100 
116 
98 
112 
154 
179 

368 

1932                                     

loa 

1933 

188 

1934                                     

225 

1935 

279 

1936                       

391 
356 

263 

1937 

252 

Medium-sized  corporations: 

1931                                             -  ---  -- 

16S 

1932 

100 

1933 

210 

1934 

242 

1935                                     .  . ... 

28S 

1936 

433 
406 

325 

1937                                 .  . 

310 

Large  corporations: 

1931                     .  .  . 

150 

1932                                                   -  --- 

100 

1933 

186 

1934 ... 

216 

1935 

250 

1936                                       .       .  

393 
388 

338 

1937    

348 

Giants: 

1931                                                         -  -- 

14a 

1932                    

100 

1933                                                         -  -- 

135 

1934             

164 

1935                                       _.     ...  .  

219 

1936      

273 
300 

215 

1937 

264 

PART  III.  RATE  OF  CHANGE  IN  PROFITS  (BEFORE  TAXES),  1932-37 

[1932=100] 


Small 


Medium- 
sized 


Large 


Giants 


Corporate  profits  before  taxes 

Corporate  profits  after  taxes  (excluding  undistributed-profits 

tax) 

Corporate  profits  after  taxes  (including  undistributed -profits 

tax) 

Depreciation  and  depletion 

Income  available  for  reinvestment  and  replacement - 


100 
100 


100 


100 

97 

97 
68 

87 


100 
9* 


Source:  Computed  from  Statistics  of  Income  for  respective  years. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


183 


8=1 


lO  OS  r-(  CO  00  t^ 
1-i  'J*  CO  O  -^  CO 


o  »c  -^  •*  oo 

■»*'  O  CO  •»!<  Tl< 


ss 


ii 


o 

ii 

Oo 


-Co 


00  T-<  C<)  IC  CO  00  «o 

Oa  Ci  Tl^  !©  r^*  CO  -H 


O5-«t<COeO>C00O5t^'*< 


^CC050t^C<t>»005 

'i"coc4->*-^'^oc<iio 


COlOt^-»*<lOrtCOOO 
r-I  ^"  r-<'  05  to  C-i  ^'  00 


i-<05coc<ifoc6-«*<id'0 


O5»o.-ic^icwcccoe<« 

odcSf-HCCCO-rlSlOt-IiO 


C005000>Ot^!»OOC^ 

ciodrHi-HiN'-Hidc<ie4 


S-gggcgggg 

-§05252221 

h'0^'-l04C^rOCOO 


=lo 
o  ^ 


C^  05  OJ 


OS  00  <C  00  «£)  CO  M 
CO  lO  Ci  ^'  -4  ,-<  r^ 


I  ■>»<  rH  03  t^  t^  CO 

i  CO  -^  lo  .-<  c^  c<i 


OS  00  CO  OS  05  OS  t- 

1-H  Tli  Tt!  CO  (H  O  t~^ 


>0  C^  OS  t^  lO  CO  OS 

ci  oi -^  rt  c^i  ec  c6 


i-H  C^  M  OS  CO  o 

OS  CO  i?4  o4  ^'  ed 


C<«  O  !>■  OS  O  CO  t>- 

CO  ■>*'•<*<  CO  c4  o  o 


,*<,_(  rt  Tf<  OS  t^  CO 

(r4  o  CO  ui  es'  o  00 


o  o  ^  cot^  00 1 
CO  OS  w  -^  ci  "*■  < 


«0  l^  >0  CO  (N  OS  < 

00  OS  ^'  e^i  -^  im'  c 


d  :ii  ?5  <>» 
o^oc-  -.  -  t-i 
^ooo^2« 


184 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13    :2; 

.S     « 
§     ^ 

^     M 

GQ 

o 

< 
w 
w 


CD  »OOi  OOt 


■8 


2^ 


i.1 


oo 


t^S- 


■*  to  CO  CO  C<  Oi  IM 

CO  — ;  .-H ,-;  r-!  ■ .-; 


OOCO^COr-HOSODOOOO 
C^i  rH  ,-^  ,-i  rH 


O05ir5'0>-I0'-<000 


CO  CO  CO  CO  00^  • 


0»0^0<N01(NOOi-l 


ocoM^-H^^c^e^co 

0ir-;^i-iT-;.-HrHf-;^ 


•  c^  Tt<  OS  ^  ^  o  05 


»0000050MOOS( 

c4  ^*  ^   •  ^   • ,_;   • , 


o  o 


a£.P. 


-^lO  O  >0  O  'O  o  2 

tjO'-i(Mc^icor'Orf>'* 
-a^ooooootj 

I— 'iCrHr^e^e^cocoCJ 


SI 


^°- 


t^  .-I  M      1  O  t-  00 


■>*<  C^  C<J  lO  (N  CO  r-t 


(N  00  CO  C^  CO  C^  CO 


iMiMiMOOCOfO 


CO  CO  IM  CO  »0  ■ 


CD  00  lO  00  CO  T>< 


in  (N  (M  CO  lo  05  o 


>*  O  CO  •*  lO  00  00 


(M  »0  C^  •<*<  0>  >0  .-H 


t-  CO  »0  O  »0  CD  CO 
rH  Ci  r-J  e4  i-I  i-J  r-< 


"  ■   2^S 

a  c  o  o-w^  > 

1   .-^ -^  ■^ -^  M  CD  ^ 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


II 


es^occi 


2o 


O  lO  (35  CO  (N  CO  IM 


OS 

o  "^ 


II 


coiacoji-H^iot^o 
.-H  .-4  CO  .-<  CO  csi  cj  05  es 


it 

Oo 

So, 

o  lo 


O'C-'i-OCOOO'CO 

eoc4csco-«}Hco.-!^c4 


t>2- 


COIr^t^C^MIMTt<Tt<o 

r-;  ,-;  <N  r-;  C<i  ,-;  rH  Tf  C^ 


lO^CStNCOCi'fCOt^ 

O  .-H  r-!  ,-!  r-i       ■  rH  C^j  ,-; 


8g 


fl  a  £3  p  a  g 

^  ^^.  o  ^-  O  uo  o  o 

^Or-HCSiMCOCO-*^ 

-o""*  o  o  o  o  o  o  tl 

P'"  o  »o  o  lo  o  m  ^ 


S°- 
0,0 

2^ 


§s 


t-o 

S5 


185 


00  t^  b»     iCO  00 

CO  r-J  M        1  -H        * 


N^I>«3rHeOCO 


>fli  000 10  o  o  t^ 
M  •«i<  c^  1-! .-;  CO 


COr-l,-l,-H> 


00  (N  CO  iM  .-H  00  C* 

c4  (ri  es  ^  .-4    '    * 


«o  o-^  c  COC5 ' 


COOlM 


186 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


a. 

CO 

^ 

W 

5U 

< 

1 

"" 

y-i 

t-< 

<to 

^) 

.:»? 

W 

2 

e 

H 

es 

< 

^ 

1 

a 

O 

P. 

<ii 

tf 

R- 

s 

P4 

(V 

> 

>^ 

^ 

n 

r/i" 

g 

m 

«j 

H 

(^ 

51, 

fe 

=? 

PM 

J2 

esipnBqojani 


9i«s8ioqA\ 


}  n  9  ui :)  J  B  d  9  g: 


S9J0JS  aiBqo 


Snun^OBjnnBui 
snoeaBiiaosi]^ 


)u9indmt)9 
uonBjJodsuBJX 


iCj9UiqOBK 


S[B 

-?9uisnoja9j  uo>i 


199^8  pUB  nOJI 


sjon 
-pojd   guipima 


jgqqna 


J9q;B9T: 


nin9i0Ji9(i 


s[BDiTn9qo 


Sut^nuj 


aodBd 


jgqrani 


S9inx9j, 


oooBqoj, 


S93t3J9A9a: 


poo^ 


I  CO  CO  t^" 


Ci  '-^  ■*■ 


O  00  «OCO 

t^  (N  Tt^  «d 


eoc^i  T-(  o(NO 

OJ  'O  lO  O  lO  >o 


Tji  lO  o  (N  -*  «o 
oi  o  CO  t^  CO  CO 


rJ't^CT>OJ00t^->*ia> 

00  c^'  c4  -^  •*<  o  >d  »o 


toiot^OMt^coooo 

Oi  O  CO  CO  >0  CO  Tj?  i^  o 


(M  ■<*<  (M  CO  05  on 
oi  CJ  N  a>  >c  o 


CO^CO0CC3i  t^ 

T-H  cr>  ui  cm'  CO  id 


r-l  CO 

»o.-h' 


OS  O  (N  t^  CO  05  lO 

CO  i-H  (M*  00  co'  »d  oi 


Tt<  cx3  oi  i^ 


OCDO 


CO  CO  IN  CS  00  00  00 
Oi  C^  ■*'  ^'  >d  CM  N." 


O  C<J  >-i      I  O  CO 

c5  CO  CO     I  uo  CO 


lOOJOOOOOlM 
t^  1-h'  M  •>#■  lO  CO 


1  »o  o 


>0  O  O  rH  lOIN 

ci  .-H  (n'  CO  ■^"  lo 


1-H  lO  CO  CO  05  <N 
d  Ci  CO  CO'  rH  lO 


I  CO  »o  ICl^ 
1  im'  >C  ,-;  rf" 


<M  c<:  t^  CO  t-  o  00  o 
^  N  TjJ  -rr  ai  t-^  o5  lo 


^CO  CO  t^ 
^CO  lO— <■ 


1--  t^  CO  t--.  t^  b^ 


(M  iM  00  IM  CO  ■* 

d  th    ■  co"    ■  (m' 


T*<t-.O5t^<N'«J<iMC0 

co"  r^  ci  ci  ci  .-H  i-i  M 


M  cDooeo 

CO  -J  .-i  r-J 


(M  t^Tf  r-l 


COt^t^OO>0(MCOr-((M 

d  ri  m"  CO  r-i  .-H  id  t^  rji 


^-  ifl  CO  CI  rfl  Tt< 


^OOOO   >0   rH   ( 

^  CO  id  ci  CO 


eo  CO  i-t  I 

(N  -M  rH  , 


CO  (M  MOO 


^^-*  rH  CO  OO  t^ 

wi-lcj    'co'cioi 


CO        00  t- 

ci  C.  ci  t>^ 


C3  IC 


O  t^  t- Tt<  ^_^C^  lO 

id  CO      *  i-i  ^     '  i-i 


^dci       ir-i 


t^  05  O  CO_ 

-co    ■  ci  CO ; 


O  00  »-i  C4  CO  C) 

■r!<    '    '  id  co'  id 


ci^_^o;  CI 

^dC^T-H  id 


00  O  "-I  M 

dcotHid 


.-H  oc^ci 

id  ci  .-i  r-I 


r-llOCO 
COrHr-i 


co^t»>o 


lO  lO  CO  o> 

ci  1-1  r-i 


lOlOO 

cdi-HrH 


«oocio» 


,  CI  CO 

ici  I-i 


CO  COTt<  CO 
t>  r-i  r-J  ci 


C<   lOTtd 

co'  -->'  r-!  . 


it>C1( 

1  CO*  ci  1 


rH  ci  rH  1 


o  o  o  c;> 

"^  ^lOOiOOiOO' 
^O^CJC-ICOCO-'^" 
rg^OOOOOO 


§*:=  a  a  CI  C  fl  O  fl 
ucDooopoog 

"^  '^o  o  o  o  lo  o  2 
fc-o^cjcacoco-*-"^ 

hJ  O  rH  1-1  CI  CJ  CO  CO  O 


S  c  <»  <» 
ji  a,  o  o 

(D    y   t-   t-i 
Q  ti   <X>   « 

*"^  ij  o.  a 


plOrHi 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


187 


-»»<«)    1    1    1 

|o     1     ;     1 

C0>0     1     1     1 

•^''^    '    !    i 

^00t»<      1      1 

^(N^CO      J 

COOJT-^OOOO 

05-^       '       '       i 

OOO      llMOO 

ooeoco     1     1 

1     1     I     !l:^ 

:     i  :  i 

1        !r-l  ICO 

OO-Ht^      llM 

i-HOO       1       1       1 

<N0O     j      i      1 

C<»rH        1        1        1 

(M^      1      1      1 

00    jo    i    1 

20  to  25  percent.— 

25  to  30  percent -- 

30  to  35  percent 

35  to  40  percent- - 

Over  40  percent 

CO 

CO 

W 

c3 

h1 

a 

o 

<D 

o 

;d 

5 
w 

« 

>H 

^3 

fH 

0) 

P, 

0 

^ 

<y 

M 

it) 

>^ 

rr" 

o 

d 

OS 

H 

O 

K 

^ 

-«1 
Ph 

a 

a 

(^ 

o 

m 

1— I  ^kC 

!oo'<»t>: 


M  CO  Tt<  CO  »o 

eo'  ®'  •^'  <o  Tti" 


■^  C4  CO  O  t^  t^ 


as  o  r^  o  o  o> 
CO  id  id  c>  CO  c^' 


■*  CO  lo  oi  eo  CO  lo 
OS  id  id  oi  o  od  Tii 


<N  c  o  ^  CO  o  e^ 
O  i^  id  id  CO  CO  oi 


C^  CO  CO  00  lO      I  CO 


Ttl    1— 1 

O  IC00  0OO5 

^'2' 

;:^^coooo 

2;; 

-*C0  05 

oo'  es  ^ 

05 

g 

lO  Tt<  IC  CO -<*<  IM  00 

OOCCCMC^  lOO- 

r-i 

lO-H 

00  CO 

05-H 

rt;c«i 

t-co 

OOO     1 

t-Jo 

T^US     j 

OOlOlOCOrH        lo 

id  05  00  c^'  -H    i  OS 

00 -H  (N  t^  O  CO  CO 

CO  ■*■  r-H  TiJ  Tf!  d  id 

Ot^OOOCOOOO 
r-;  CO  CO  Csi  CO'  V  (N 

OfNOO 

C3  CO  CO  id 

COiC 

id  !  12  N 

O  C^  t^  t^  r}<  O  lO 

2S'^2;;:IS2 

C^  CO  t^  lO      1  00  OS 

id  T^'  CO  CO    I  N  co' 


00  rH  -^  lO  00 
rji'  oo"  CO'  »■  TjJ 


oo  IM  OS  O  OS  -^  lO 

im"  co'  c^'  id  o4  rH  t>: 


O  O  ■>*<  OS  W  CO 


(N  t^OCOCO 
d  '*<■  (N     '  oi 


t^  lO  t>.  lO  lO  rt  ■* 


OOOCOO        (M 
d  IN  (N'  (N  O  CO 


C0CO(NCO^ 

■<i<  id  co'  --i  i-i 


00  CO  ^-  OS  -^      00 

d-;  '.-;  'o  ' 


lOCOOS  CO  o 

•<*  >d  CO  I-H*  TJH 


00  t^  CO  OS  lO  O  lO 

d  '-i  (N  Tt<'  CO  i-H    ■ 


CO  t>.  ic  lO  c^l  eo 

(N  id       '       '  C<l  rH 


CO  <M  CO  O       Ir^ 
00      '  co'  S>J  O  CO 


■^  lO  t^  CO 
es'  CO  r}<'  co' 


I-I  i-H  OS  CO  04 
d  idr-i  CO 


t>.  OS  oco  e^      lo 


03  lOrH  I-HIN 

d  CO .-;  rt'  i-H 


)  C^  CO  C^l  lO  iC 


CO  OS  (N  N  00  C^  • 


1  CO  M  •<*<  CO  lO  o 


OOOOi-H  O      lO 

d  rt'  .-H  r-!  rt    I  iri 


CO  t^  OOO  lo  00  o 


I  CO  lO  N  t^      t(N 


Tt*  t^  OS  CO  o  CO  i-H 


CO  OS  C>I  iC  •*  00  CO 


lO  t- <N  CO  t^  00  cq 


iM  OS  "-^  C^      I  CO  lO 
rH      ■  r-i  .-<       I  -h'  t-I 


O  OS  CO  CO  Tji  " 

c<i  .-H  ^  .-;  oi . 


iHr-l(NTl<CO 
^*  ^  ,H  rt  (N 


t~  CO  O  t^  CO  CO  CO 

Ci  r-J  cm'  r-I  r-l'  rt  rH 


^  fl  ci  S  o  S  « 
^  o  o  o*^*^  9 

f-~,  "^  "^  ■^  (N  CO  X 

^  M  Tf!  00  i-l  ■-.  O 


1     '  -i-^  c!  d  fl 


"  (-1  t-  <p  c.  & » 


<MCC^ 


Pes-*  00 


£i  fl  C  a3  o  o  « 

P  <N  ■*  00  .-I --I  O 


X2  X 


®>2 


188 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


00t^t^C0CO(M?0CCC<100O00t^O5^iM 
(N  ri  i-i  rH  CC  C<5  C4  r-i  e-i  -^  --;  r-;  C4  1-i  <m' 


(M  Tt<    I  o  o  m 

0000      i<000 
I  CC  ■*■  CO 


r-  (M  lO  ^  -M  05 1^ 

CO  t-  r^  Tt<  >«  r--(  o 


C<»  C^  rH  r-l(M  tN  r-l(M  (N  C<l  (M  "-H  r-l  I-KN  I  I-l  i-(  »C  lO  >0  CO 


(Mr-I^  (MrHrH^IMt^fN'^-^CTl 


C^  IM  i-H  i-l(M  (N  rH  CI  IN  IM  (N  rH  I-l  i-H  <N  I-H  1-1  lO  ■*  lO  »C 


<N00O^«505O-^0J>Cli35C»t^i0t^ 
i-lt^C0lMOi000t^«5t^-*O(NOi-( 

i-i  CO  1-H  T-i  >-;  (N  r-<  1-1  ,-;  IN  CO  CO  CO  »0  c<5 


«15 


iOO(N(NCOCOCO(NcO-<*<0500CO-«*< 
iT-IIN^rHi-IINi-IOi-lrHlOeOCOi-t 


SO 


T-HO— iciT-ii-i'*co(Nt-icoeOTj<t^i 

OOOOOOCOOO.-IOOO. 


gS2SSSSfe8§^^g^§ 


OO      100      lOO 


0.-iiNt-(Oi-i<C(Nt-iO. 


<N  IN  IN  IN 


00   O 


•<*IOt^(NCOC-3000000CO'-lt^'NOlO       iOIN00-*>O>O 
Or-iOOOOO--^  OOOOOOOO      iOOO.-<(NO 


:S2^^I 


i^to^oooo»o-#QOO<r>ot^cocOT-io 

.-lO^Oi-ll-lr-lC^r-li-IOOOr-KN 


1— I  >£.  o  Oi  o  03  CO 

CO  O  IN  (N  1-1  CO  IN 


OOOOCOO'-i'-iCOINirD<N(N(N 


as 


OOaOi35'.0  0003ThlcOlOO-^-<*H^t^lOcOTt<T^OiC-rt<0<NtO 
^^^^,-l(NCS(NINCOINr-lr-lr-llNOINrH^OCOCOTt<IN 


^r^O300(Ntcit^t>t^tot--aiio«oi^ 

i-ldOO'-lr-ti-t^^T-tT-i-^^-lr-lT-tr-i 


.2^ 


Sb 


1<»OOCOI>.CO'*CO'-I^COO 


co^cococoiococDi»ioiy3Ttiioio» 


eg 

M    O 


lOOOt^lN— <0 
O  1-1  O-"^  CO  lO 


■^OJ'OiOCOOlOtN'-lOOlOOO'— lOSlOiNt^OOCOlNOBt^OSOO 


■*INCOCO-*i>Oi-lCOCO'OCO 


00 --<  05  lO  IN  t^  00 
r-^  IN  O^  CO  IN  O  1-1 


CO  <N  t^  CC  Ol  lO 


IC<|lNt-IC3rHCO>OC»< 


ssSi 


oO"-^.o      oo"-io      oO^.O 

SeC^S^^-     |€4(M««-^-     i^S''*^^" 

"3  —  OCJ.S'O-'^ofcS'^-^oS'^'^-^^?^!^ 


ooRo 


as 


b£^ 


ga 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


189 


r-iMi-lNr-KNlMCSCO       i^r-Ir^i-Irt^        ,^       ,       .^c^^*^- 


O3C«5>OCO00IO00W00 
Tji  lO  <m"  «■  C^'  CO  CO  (N  00 


Tj<CO«>C500>CO^OO'-l'— ICD-— IrHO 

t>  00  C3  (m'  00  TtJ  Tt<  <>i  CO  00  ro  Tji  c^'  c«5  >-h  r-I 


t-COCC'^OT»te>^VO«>.-HOiTj<OrH(MOrt 

l^(NC0O00r-ll0O^OlOO^t^C<l01t^ 

odeoNcic<ieoco(N'e^eoco(Neo.-H(>irH(N 


(COrt  rH       iCSNNCO 


<N  (N  C^'  c4  (N  <N  C>i  Ci  Tji  csi  CO  ■>ji  ^ 


Iit2!^^t!tS;r!fc2:z!:r'*'"^'^^^<^<^"'3oooiro->*<rHO-^^e^oco 

-Ht-.04cOt>t-OC^00005.-nO^OO<MCOO-.  o.-ics'Ot-cocot^t-ocooi 

co'  (N  (H  r4  M  (H  CO  ci  e<i  CO  CO  .-H  e^  ,-H  M  rH  c^  00  ^'  c^  ci  c^  l^^  .-H  cs  e^  CO  c-i  CO  co'  T}I 


^S?52^g^2gS?5^^§8S§SS2:8§§522§§82S88S8§&§§2gggS^22S 


SS2fcSS!52Sr:!JiS2SSS3222£SS5e2£3i«t:<»«><^'^oo(Mco^(Nco^icor-i^o.-H.-i(Nt^T»<.-ieo'<*<>o 

OOrtOOOOOr-(OOOiMe<«000(NOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOCOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 


>0<NCOt^— it^fNtOCOOOOOi-iOOOCOOOOOCOrHOOOIMOOOOOOOOoSoOOCONN^- 


Sj?      IS      1      IZ!!2E2J5      '  CO  rH  00  to  CO  CO  O  t^  OO  00  <N  OO -;  Tt<  5;  Tf<  t- to  <©  Oi -*  CO  O  O      .  CO  r-iM  co -i  ^  CS  (M  t~- 

TfO       lO        1        1  i-H  (N  F-(  O       '  <M  r-I  O  O  COr-<  C<)  ^  i-l  O  ^  T-KM  IM  OrH  IM  ^  ,-(  O  O  rH  OO       1  M  ■*  (N  ^  <N  CO  ^  Tjl  (N 


O      1      lO      I  .-I  rH  r-I  CJ     lOO      lO     iCOOOi-iOOOO      iCOOO^O     lO     1      lOO^O     1  I-H  r-I  ^  ^ 


s^^\ 


oooeo>oeocO'«*<c 


T-IOCS|i-104i-lt-lT-(i-Hi-HfHi-Hr-li-l< 


iN05050t^t^e<iT*< 


IC^rHrHrHCOrt'-l^. 


Si^^^ggi; 


)00CO<MCOCO(MCOfOe^lMCO00CO(MCOCOC-»COCO000OCOCOCOe 


iOt^COCSTti05C^Oe^0505COC>100l^'-HioOt^>-lOO»Oa0030t^'<ti03-<*'t^CDOOCS-*C^COCD(MtO»OcO— 105'— it^i-it^cO 


»000«OCOIMCO>CICO«OOOTt<lClOJOOOO 


'-HioOt^>-lOO»Oa0030t^'<ti03-<*'t^ 

t-HMOS'— IOOi-It-Ii-H050i— li— li-lrH 


OOlM'-IC0(M'tlr-lr-l00rtO'-IIN05C0Mi-l 


t^  CO  CO  t-~  to  -H 

TJ^^COCOOO 


t^  rH -^  lO  lO  •>*l  t^  (M  CO  ■*      iO> 
CO  .-H  O  CO  >-l  rH  r-I  O  CO  (N      iiM( 


r-1  rH  rHr-lC^  rH 


_j  O  ^  »0  lO  t>.  00 
I  CO  CO  00  CO  »o  t^  o> 


ii 


ig 


oo°8 


lO  O  rH   O 


r-1  *i  -»  r; 


SOrHO  icO-HO 


^S^S- 


O  O  -w  ^'-;  o  O  ■ 


lO  C5  --I  O 


in  o  >-<  < 


S'^^oail'3-^oo-2'^-^oo5'C*^oS^'2-^oc55'S-^oSii'5*^o 


oaQO>ofloo>ofl=5gf*cOoo>oCoo>oGoo>oaoo>cCoo>oCoo>oCoo> 


190 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


(M  C<5  03  CO 
CO  CO  C^  CO 


•<*<  Ci  (M  to 
(m'  iM*  cs  o4 


cooo 

r-l  -^  CJ3 

c4e-4  T-i 


-^Oic^ioe^coooco 
Tjiescoco-^^cocico-^coc^c^ico 


C0'#OCDO-«t«CeCi<M»-^C0O(Mt^i-iOCC00r0<0 

o(N050^C5c^r^cioocD-^»c-*a>coa>iMCT>co 

■^'  CO  CS  CO  r»<  CO  CO  CO  tH  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO'  Tji  C^  •<«'  ■^'  CO 


cocococort<eo<N(Neoeococ<iiNco 


<^ 


Ttl'-H-^OCOl^rH-^C^OCOr-lfNCO 

OOOOOOOOO'-IOOOO 


I^COlCrt5OCqTj<t^00tS!NC0t~-00t^(N»O0000 
IOOO--IOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 


^  m  g 


t^CC— l?CeOt^OOOCOOO"*OCOrHO 

c^->*<cor-i,-ie>5cofOi-iiMc05C>coc<io 


S0 


O  to  T-^  1-1  o  t^  o  - 


S?5SS 


id  CO  coo 

.-I  (MOO 


J^'*iO«^CD(M'#t^-* 

OCO^OO— IrHOTl 


<M,-(>-H.-l(M^O'-ir-l.-<rtO^T-lC<).-IOC^C-10 


s^ 


O0b--^COCOOOO'-ICO<35<M 
ilMClCOCO-^COCOCOCOIMCO 


a^ 


238^; 


.iOTt<Tfi-lt^iOIMiO(N05CO>0 


oa 


s.g 

"Ceo 


>lr^u000C0iO'#>-iO5CTiiOrt<t^C0 

)  es«  CO  t^  05  Oi  o  ■*  t- ■■  ^ 


§§^! 


>-lrH         ,-l(M,-l 


^3  2 


lO 


oo=lS 

CoOt-iO 


ooog 

lO  O  "-J  o 
1^^  o««- 


, o o ^.o    ,oo    ~o    ,o 

.lOO—^O      .loO'— lO      ,io 

ij_,*^0««-      i(_*'^C««-      il-i''"C€^         ~  ^  ~  -      - 

^'S-SoS-g'S-^oo^'rJ-^ofe^'C-^ofc^'O^ooi^'a'^ooi^'S-^o® 
oCloo>oCoo>oOoo>oOoo>oQop>cGoo>oGoot> 


o 

O     1 

I    . 

tf 

h  ' 

w 

« 

a  J 

p 

H 

0,0 

^ 

aa 

b 

*^  3 

P 
^ 

^^ 

< 

O.O 

^ 

;^^ 

.3  c 


^-3 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


191 


O  >-<  O  "3  CO  CO  c 


Ot^CC00O'-l<M005Cl(M00Ot^00t- 


iS^JOlNOOCDI^OOCCOt^t^m 


■~  OOfO  < 


'iJ2Si2929S"^''"^°o*'ci'«i<'fooo5Mt^eocoo«oc<M<oe<i<oo 

>0(M05CO<DOO«DCO'<*'0>OiOlOCSC^-<l<t^rHOi-l50^(N^OcJf-H^ 


■^c^ecco-*eciMC<j<Mc<3-*coiOt>.-'jtc<«e<ie^cs(M( 


Jo^co'i<coec'*rj<Tt<cocc'^'<»*-*'<*<T»<Tj<T»<ioeoeo'*iou5e»3co^'0 


05r^DOt^'-HiOiO'>*iOC<lt^OMM<Tti(X5?OCOt^t^COu^'>*<OiOOOT*<05003-^OiOiOOc«2-*iCMCO.--i05t^toabr>j(— ir^oA-»M 

cccor^Mco-^c^^-0(^^col005oo>0(»c^^-oc«cftoc^oo.-l^-lo^e^riHM'5<cocs^:HicwKoS 
M  (^^  c^  cc  c^  CO  c^  M  ci  CO  .-I  c^  c^  »d  r-H  c4  cs  (^^V^  c^  oo  lO  o  rH  oi  ->«<■  l^^  CO  T>;  T»;  ^ 

^^,Hl-<1-H.-^e<i.-H.-HrtO.-He^lrtO'-Hr-<OrHrHCOOOOCOOeS.-HrHOOC^rHrHOOl-HOOOO.-HfHOOOi-iSoO 


S!::l25SSSS52Ji!SS9S5Sr^SS?3^::iSSS3Sa2:SS£222SS2!'^'''«=^ocococo(M05(Neoeoo-<*<iNco(Nio 

0'-iOOOOOOOOOOOrHOO'HOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO>-lOOOi-10000?i^OOO>-< 


40C0OC0C0.-1  IMOO 
t-H  ,-(  CO  CO --KM       ■  -^ 


iMooOi-it~»ioc^iocococ^'-<i-i«;co< 

■-l<Me-l(MO.-IC0050C--»i-CCOr-lO^(NC 


I  CO  CC  lO  CO  01  CO  < 

>  c<i  ^  CO  ■*  e^  rt , 


•CO'HiCINlNOOCOCOt^ 

<Oi-lr-lrt.-ii-lOCO-«»<i-lO 


■<*  rt  «0        Tti 


I  coo  00O5  t^  ^  o 

I  e^  CO  rH  (N  .-H  CO  CO 


'  O  t^  CO  lO  t^  M 
I  t^  CO  ■«<  C^  CO  Tjl 


t^iOOiCOOOJOlkOOcOOtOt^ 


OtOt^t^OCOOOOI:-COO"505t^O>OCO-^C^O'*«Ot^«><McO»0.-ia)COOe<l-HicOTt<t--ob-0 

5oes«o«o«Dr--^50t^t>.cocoooojeo<»o>i>055D<r)t^«oooocD'*05c»«oaoe^ot^oooc^050»H 


or^oocoosr^i-ir-HO 

e<l(N.-((M,-(0(N.-iO 


§8? 


lo  00  to-^ 

.-lr-((NO 


«c•o^<»o^^»o.-H^-t^lO«OTt^T-HTt^ccooeoo5e^^05^'C^cotot^ooc^l-l1--l<^^(^^^oo>o^-o■>*^^o^-C!5TJ^co^-.l^^lC< 
i-HescSi-Ht-<.-^c^e<irH.-H7-HCScscsrHc^ci(N(N^i-HcorM,-i,-icococococococococococo'<i'-^'ococseococoMCScocot 


:  M  1 1°  1 1 ;  M  M  M^  M  M  i  M  M  M  i  M  1  M  M  1 ;  I  M  i  I ;  M 

i  i  i  !  !^  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i*^  i  i  i  i  i  i  ;  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i  i 

S?5J5g 

S^S5  :§^ss  isgs  i  is^s  i  ;E;5J§s;s  is^J^s  ;s?^2S  isggg  iggg§  i 

*■"       ""* 

i*^      "^  i          i  i          i  i            i            i            i            i            i 

_.sSi 

«^cs^^- 


fc.^  069- 
O   COO   > 


dots 

ioOr-HO 

o  coo 


0  o  Ro  ;  0  o  ^-o 


i§2 


Jl 

f>  o  coo  >  oCOO 


"*^  1-1 
o  o 


doRS 

10  0  T-;  o 


cCoo>oGoo>cCoof>oCQo>oCoo>oCoo>oa 


--J  cj  o  «  t^ 


-a 
£3 


192 


OONCENTUATION  OF  ECONOMIC  TOWER 


■^1 
5| 


t^t^Oift      ikOTf<OOJ      iOC«iO'»      lOiTft^fO     IQO-J-H.-I      c^O^O 

o>oe5o     i«o^55>o     'C^ccajTt"     iecM-<-^     iSccoo    .ub^^t^ 
T^■e«5^^-;     les<Ne4ed     1(n^(N-^     leoMcoeo    lcc«Mri<     leoTtiwco 


»oeO'»j!-»i5o6«oNM'«'<oc«9C^e«Jcoc^'"3eoe<5C'5co»oe«5c<3ecM3Tj<eoN 


'-trH00i^0C^0O00-H0»-'OO-HOO0OOOO0-<C^OO«O 

c5 


«o^ 


>oooc5oooooooooooooooooooO'^ooocoS 


g§ 


«0  i-H  OIN'^JllOVOrtfrO.-l— <O0C05.-im».TeMNI^lC06Q00M«ff'^'^< 


S^ 


si 


•-1 


^a 


73  o 


ab 


^  ft 


Oseo-^  itotcrj*  it^oOOt^      lOOOWO      'OOr-,0000     lOOCCt^t- 

•>««^«)0      >OC^OO      i^O^O      ir-iON—i      10.-I00      ir-<0'-<i^ 


ooo^-c<^?p■«*<Tf<oo«c^5»0{«^os^J^?05C^•>*<•^}<o6^^»coQt^c^a5^>•^cc^o 


S^! 


!  ,-1  lO  05      I  OJ  ■^  O  £ 


S?5c^S  ls»oi 


o^5■«J<o^^l5l5cJ■*«5oo^ot^oc>oo>>o«o<^>»ooob^~<o»u:>■<J<o6ob 


t~<o»u:>-<j<o6deco»o 


J?§-'S  '?S-^'S    RS-S  ;SS 
*'>S"=^-r  i«^^^-~  '^^S*^-   "^?^ 


c5  <»   ••   , «?  ?j  «f>  _r   1 4^  ?i  *^  _- 


'-  I  ^ 

u  I   a 

-0  w  3 

f*  «  o 


COXCENTaATION  OF  ECONOMIC  I'OWKH 


193 


1.90 

1.22 
2.51 

3.28 
2.62 
3.34 
3.32 

J^ 

'5^S 

s 

? 

s? 

^2 

S 

1: 

^ 

r^ 

5£ 

?; 

• 

oo<c 

s 

(N 

MOC 

1.64 
2.09 
2.09 
1.60 

S2?^SS;5teE:2S^S?5SSS:SS!j  jSloSJS 

C4  i-J  N  M  r-5  r-!  rH  W  .-; 

CO 

^^^?i?^^^[i^'£2^?t?^v: 

S2|gg::Sf:2l:J^ 

■«<C<C<CC-9<»OCSCC-.J-«CTt<C4eMCC«C 

^<N^^^-^^^^^ 

S:2§S;:3SSS§gSSSSS       SS5l::SS2S2gS^3?322S2SS2S2?522 

^.^.r^^.^^^-.s 

g§SS§2S§gJ2S§§Sg 

S^::]S§;^^85??22§r^^^SS      S^2?SS;SS$S5)2.tgf:!Sg2S5^^g{^?;?SiqS? 

:S2ig^S5£{^ 

5 

^9^^^^^^^^^^^^^^ 

:*223?l:2g5SS?:3:2S2^S§;:^{£S2^2gS 

;=:^_s?5  8?:  ???:?/ 

SS{512S882t2g^§8SS8S§ 

^^^^^^^3^^^'^^^^^^^^^^^'^^s^^^ 

5o:S2f^SS^g8£5J3 

" 

'^''^ 

ScJSSS 

SgS§ 

Si:;2?; 

SSS§§SS§S2gS8S§SSg88;:3Sg2 

8SS  S  gSSSS 

_^ 

t-,0<-i'-i'-i(NO»-i^CS?i.-irteNf<  OOCO'-i0OrHOCOOOOOiNr-iMO-«<0Or-ic50O00O0O0rHSo 


?§?l?S5^i^^?^§?J??^?:??J       28§S2SgSlSggSSS2SSfeS2S?3?;i«;^S82i::2888feS 


POOOOt^PCOl'OC^KO.-HOaipOliO  rtra>0'>*cu50>iOt>.i-iOl>-«OOt0UJ^iC'*iOl»0000C5tC«0C^C>»i»^'Or-ioC-lC»u? 

e<«D.-(C^<M'»<i-f<»<C0>O.-.O5?(C«-H  COOt--ICO«C.-iOOM-«»'CSO>--l(Nu5cSO^««005CO«5.-l<£)Ttfr-l(MlO>OC»l^rH(MC> 


S^S?J 


.-lCO.-l.-<r-lC>-tr-lClr-iOO>-H.-OOOOr-i(Mprt-^ 


f5o^     M     —.OO'-if* 


t'Coe^'C^.-it-'^O'OfoesQ'o.-i          »oo5coi©ocoocO'»<M-*a>cccca>'-i'<ti<»Q— 'C^oov«»< 
esF-5''c^.-4''i-<esr-<'*'^  


82g52^8^?J?? 


:  :  :8 J  :  !  ^8  ' 

I       '  _'  O  S'       1       I  _'  O  Ci 

,  ^,  CI  "y.*  __^    ,  wt  f  <  <^  _; 


i^d'Sg  i^^o's'o  ;g5'd8d  iSo'go 

^«&Sl£S    i'^'^Sgss     f^'^-^^J?.     ?<^^?2 


;8o 


lis 


oCop^oCQO^oOop;-  OOpOt-oCpO>oCpO'K-oCpO>oCppi^oCpC>oCpO> 


O 


194 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POAVBR 


'3    t«    g 

=3   CJ   >^ 


i| 


-So 


^1 


a^ 


13  S 


i-l.-iO^C^I05C0OO'0-<^( 


»0  lO 
CO  CO 


iioao.-HTf4    lOcoosiN 
1  e^  --<  oi  M    1  <m'  oi  .-f  M 


I(^^(^^c^T-^^co^-lrH(^^(Ml^^(^<^Ofocc^oco(^^coco^^co    i(NCSt-<(NCMi 


(^■^^^C^,-i,_,,Hi-i,-l(NfOi-l(Mt<3(NC^(MC^INCOeOC0(M      iO^C^N(M(N.-ti-li-tlM 


J_ICOT-ll-((MrH(Mi-lrHOi-llM'-l'-lOOOOOOOOOO       l^eOl-Hr-lT-lrtr-lrHOO 


(M(rocoiOr-i<OCD-^OTt<COTfi05cDTt<01I<lt^'-Or-iOst~.iC-^      rCOOO"— lOOOsoOt^C^'^ 
r--t--S-cO00c5:OCO(M(NO5<£>CCa0(N00^w00O500^iO00      lOOOiOOOJl^asOOOOOOCO 


!COC<50<M'-l<Nr^(M(MCO'0(Mi-H«>iO«5«5?Ol-OOVCT>      I'^COTt'COt-COCOC^COCO 


)0  r-I  O  O  O  O  O --H --H  O  r-i  r-1  O  O  O '-I  O  O  O  O      I      I      I  O  C  O  O      lOOC^OO 


OOOOl-lOO'HOOT-IOOOi-l'-l'-l'-lr-d-Hl-H.-ICSrH        IrHOi-l'-t.-lT-IO'-lr-l. 


toir5f-5COcDc3O5t:^'Ot^C5rOCCr»-^00->ti'«ti'— lOcDMt^b-      iCO®t^OiOOOQ005-^00 


I  ^  O  --I  C^        I  (M  O  rH  <M  I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  195 


■  (Nr-i(Mr-<(M<NCCC^(NCSeMCOIM        (NCO      i—i^^rt      ie^<Ne^lM(M 


i©-^o«>oai>-i^05ccr-co-»t"»t"t^»^fct^oor^<oc;cs»03 
ojcoeooo>oa>o<ca>r-<t^0'^>-i>oooo>oa>-^oot^05rt 


c^rHiM(N(N(N(Mr-ieoeoc<ii-i.-(iM(N(Nr-<rHe><e'ie^N(Npq 


??2g§Sg5§SSS 

s 

g 

COCOCOCOC 

S 

S2?,§8 

SS8S 

fi::^^^ 

^8i5^ 

feS 

-* 

SS 

3;s^s§ 

i;??l:2 

(MCS 

.-i(N(Nes<NC^<N(N<N 

" 

" 

(Ncsc^e^rt 

C^  (N  (M  C^  (N  (>) 

^  c4  (N  C^  Oi  TjJ  im'  (m'  c^  c^'  ■^'  cc  ^ 

e^Mio 

l-H  1-1 

^r-ie»s<N(NiM(Nro 

"^c3 

««g^g«SSS 

05 

- 

g§S^2^ 

SS2?5^SS2^S 

s:2;2^;q 

QOc©Mt-l>i-H 

8!::5J 

^i::feS 

^222 

<  t^  33  O  lO  u-5  t^  05  X  t-~  < 


l-l  r-l<M  T-l 


CCCC0050CCOOt^CO'.OiMCONOiCC-lC^C5  00(MC^-HO      i»OCOtC»t--*iOe0O3r000MOrt0C«t^t^'CO-^OC0'<*'a» 


COOirOlNiCiOiOIMiCIMOlt^-^l^r-iCS'-iiMC'l.-HOC'JSOJCO 

OI>.OO05I^O0000'OC0iC00C»'-CO>O001MOTT't-C00Q 


OCO'OOC«3030COlC-li-(Tt<(MCCTtiCDCOOC'-'CC> 

rtt^csoi-irtcsico.-irHrt03r^«t^«OGoo3'*i-^ooi 


•SSfe2Sg?35§S§&8SS§5^§2?:i22S?3  ',^22SSSS^S2S^Sg^§§S§SSSg;^: 


10r-<rt(N.-<00^0<r-lOl 


■«^0O(N  >o»o 


oc^rt■^MTtl^-o«<:»«c^^ec■*o^OiTt<(^^^-.oo5^DOco5C>ooa>c^t^co'CTJ<:ooa>oecooc<^XJ<■^CTl 


0«3CTi01QOCO(MCTiOO»OT-l050COOt^>00005 


(^^iOt■-cso^~ooo5'-lcooo^5cococo■*»o(Nr}^ 

CSOrtCS'OC0O"^00-*00C<-^00'«"'-"(NO 


•oio:ot^oco«i'*t^ooic.-ir-ico-rcooo-*(N(N>ct^t^    >oO'<*<iroooiOT)<oorH'^pc2'-C'SS!S;2SS2f?SS2f25S 


gis  iidis  '444b  iggis  iisis  lidil  ^idip  ^idii  !i§ii  iigii 


•a  a 


196 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


W  (N"  (N  C>i  (N  M  «N  i-H  (N 


C>^IMIMC^INC^      i(M(MC«5rH<N. 


!i-.ccooi-i»ot^c><r>-«*<.-i 


52 

O  o 


COCOCOCOCOMMt-iC^ 


C^  M  CS  CO  C<i  C^'  1-H  C^'  Ci  C^  --H  C^'  (N  T-4  ^  r-J  ,-H  CO  i-I  rt  T-l'  C<i  rH  r-I  c6 


.   ^  _^ -n  00  <r>  oi  i^ 


(NC^C0(NfO(Me<lrH(N 


N<N(MC<IC^CSC^(Ne^lM. 


lOiOOCOOr^fCiOI:^ 


OOIMC^«CJt^>-IC00003a>OOCTi(NGOOiOOOCQOOCOi-l05'-'e>» 

r-IM<MT-lO'-lC><.-IOOl-IOO.-Hl-.0'-<CO.-H,-iO^IMrHl-IO 


oo-^ooco-*eoo30ooo 
co'<*'TficoeoTt<Ttnoco 


O'ooi,-(oooiccoooo<»io>c-^eo- 
T-iesT-(>-iooc^-H^oiMMiMe>it» 


CC  CO  ^  T— *  05  CO  CO  i-H  05 

ooocoor^-OiaxN-* 


co>CrHO'-Hooo(NoO'-i»oo5'<*'»oo5C^Tt<e^ioeo>-i.-'>-ico 

Ot^(NO«0050iiOOO'*OOOOTKCOeOt-Oi-<*'CO«D05C»<0-!jf 


§1 


01(M^<NOCO.-l«)05t^-^(MI^'^-^-^0<NM'r}.QC«DT-l{0 
OO.-l.-IO'-iOrHOC0O'-HOOOOOOOOOrt,--O 


^a 


i>OC2IM'-<'^C(0(N-5t< 


lOOOOOOiOOOOOOOOO 


U5r-l-HO<0'-ieO>-HCO 


COir>rHlOTt<r-ltC>^«^00eSrtCO!N(MN^.-IMN0Oi-l>ClO5( 


a>> 


C0CCt^C0t^>O05-Ht^ 

iCi-((Mioiocoe-iiooo 


cor-iiortOOiM^cO'eoiM(Mt^r^oco-^r^-^t^covc(^^ooe^ 

-- C^  CO -^ -^  "  CO -"t  M*  •'ti  ^  CO  CO  Tf  »o  ^  CO  CO  CD 


r-l  lO  rt  00  IM  ^ 
T-H  (N  »0  lO  CO  1-1 


tOOM-^OOINOi-iCO 


(N05«0< 


(MOt-HCOCOCOO^CIOOCIi 


^d8g   i^ciSg  i^dSg   'ddSo   ;^'c§g  i^o'Sg   ;8o'Sg 

«^»occg      'S^'OCOg      ,^^co^       c^ioco^       €^-»-"C0O       </=k>OCO^      ^ICCO^ 
^€«-^|g     l^^^^^     ITh^'^^s^     i  u*^^e^     ITI^^I?     i T,*^*^^     iTT^^      ^ 


ooL^'-:ooo.~a^cOt^'-2<3jOOL^'— >c-ioo 

TOf^-^-M     gC-Q+-4J     t-rar-j4_,^J     g_gn3+^+3     grt^^-^     -ro.Q*^+^     -C^.Q+^+3     2 

oaoo>oCoo>ccoo>oaoo>oCoo>oSoo>oOoo> 
"  '/;- O  cr  1-j  «^.- 6^  O  H  h-*  «fr  «/=•  O  E- 1-' €(9  «/=■  O 


1    t, 

£    .5 

tT 

a 

cs       -c 

a 

03 

1    - 

a 

'^^ 

^     -c    . 

"3 

'■'^ 

ber  and 
ned. 

umber  a 
material 

Es 

If 

o 

ca  fcju 

« 

o 

ag^ 

Ph 

K 

K 

3 

S 

c" 

?3' 

*5l 

h-lO 

^1^ 

t> 

> 

CONCENTRATION  OF  EiCONOMIC  POWER 

ec -"i*  l^  (M  c«3 -^  ■<f  t^  o  cc  CO  t^  o  >o  1 -rf  >o  lo 'i*  I  o  T»<  oc  r-  1 1- co -^  co  i  »o  i-i  •<*<  t^  •»><  o  t-h  t^  co  i  »o  co  o  o 

CO  i-H  T-l  «0  IM  0>  00  «0  CS  CS  O  TT  <M  lO      I  O  CO  00  >0      l  i-l  00  50  t^      iTfCOOOOO      I  CO  OO  •-I  ":>  O  CO  ^  00 -^      I  i-c  00  ■^  05 


M  e^  (M  (N  rH  >-i  T-1  .-I  !N  .-I  e^  e^  CO  rt    knc^c^w    ic^      .-ic^ 


io-*ooc^'«»coicooo'«*icoc^tD<N05oO'«*iicot--a>co 
05eot^t^'^toioooc^i-H02'*oa>o>raco-'j<t^oo<-((Nt^<N 

N  c^  e<i  c^'  co'  es  i-i  CM  l^^  CO  oi  CO  •^'  (N  c^  CO  oi  c^  co'  CO  co'  CO  es  CO 


(COOOOO'^CDOSOSCOeOCOCOlOOTfOOlCCOOOO 
l--t-»lt3-<J<loeOC0CO00«O005O00»O«C»CCO'<»<«OCT> 

c».-;cic<ieo»4c4i-HrHi-4coc<ic^coT»;c<ic^c<i«><N 


i'S'-^OO-^OtCCOOO'f'C' 


C^<N(NesCOCSCNi.-'C^(N(M(N<NINIMCOiMe^COCO(Nrtr-l00 


TJ^c5o■^lO«o•^co^-TtlC^!^^^^c^^lCr-(r-l^e^^o 
pi  M  (N  ci  co'  i-(  rt  r-i  r-i  rH  CO  CO  c-i  CO  tt  e^  w  M  ri  c^i 


^05C0C^iO^O5O:r-< 
■<|J"<*<-^CO»OCO>-<COCO 


,e^<o-<*>Tt<ococoooo(Nt^cot^t^O'ocoo5 


O0CC0-<*i05l000«O»OC0-*iO00OI 


I  CO  (M  < 


:  00  (N  00  O  00  l>- 


oeocoo5ict^0'005ooio( 

rHO—IOC^OOOOOOl 


SSgJS 


C>0>-iOOOOOO< 


Q005.-(OOCT>-<*<t^i-iTf05aio;t^t^-^cooi5Doo«ooo«o<c.-t 

T-IOCS«.-(l-IO'-Hr-lT-(.-lO'-<<N>-(WOCO.-HeSr-lOl-lN 


»^oo-^-<*<»oo;"5ooo50oOs-ie^t^coco»0'«j<05cocooo< 


I  r*<  lo  o;  »o 

I  to  t>.  •^  i-l 


it^«DCs?DoootO'-i«o«;o:«o'«too 


^  t^  >0  00  CT>  t^ 


^<NcOTiHrt< 


S^^S 


io-*oot^coCMoO'<*ics^rte^e^<c^ 

ICOCOrHCOM'rt»OC4Tr<C<©'^^CO'* 


t-l  .-I  1-1  CO  CO  IM  CO      iCM.-c(Nr-l 


)C^«C00<MMt^C<l«CC^00T»<r^»C'<*'Tft^«O 
KN.-10— i<NO>-iO'OO«CC0f-.(MC0C^^W 


<Orf<NvOCMCOOO< 


,OOr-,,-iOOO.-0000000 


t^^osoO'OO'OCfcwc^i^occ-^^-iesr-rticr- 

,_|,_,Hl-l.-l.-lOO^'-H<Nl-l<NeS«0'-0'-r-(rt 


)  »  e^  5C  00  icic  's-  • 


;^oSg  iSdSg  ;g'd8o  ig'o§§  i^dSg  is'oSg  is'oSg  ;^d8o  ;§o|g 

'-;^^g  i^^s^i  it^i^i  it^^i  it^^i  't^^i  '^^^i  ;t^^i  ;t^^i 

^x)-^-^  fc^-o-"-*^  fc^Td-^-^  feS^:;-"-^  oii'C-*^-^  fei^T:-^-^  S^'C-"-^  fci^-c*^*^  o^'Q*^-^  S 
oaoo>oOoo>oCoo>oCoo>oGoop»oi=oo[>oCoo>oCoct>cCgo> 


'^ 

B 

S 

c8 

1- 

6jO 

1 

§) 

3 

ti 

^ 

pSH 

« 

« 

M 

M 

M 

262698— 41— No.  9 14 


197 


198 


OONOENTEATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


>OOt^OOOt~-<tlCNOOCO 


>0  ■*  CO  i-H  00  CO  t 


0  01-^        .-H        IM  ' 


05  >-.  — I  rt  C-J 


— C  r-H  ^  r^e^ 


0^^000(NOOOOOOOO^(M>-('-H.-lO'H'-iOOO<N'-iOC 


P   4.  X 


i-(.-H(M^-Hr-^(Nr^Or-lOOQOO'-<^«Or-i^<M.-(^(>»{MOOOOOIMW(NIM(N 

oocoooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo 


l':00^'*01(MO>-H(N>-HOt^t^COC<3»0>#^rHWTj<c<3t^TflOCO'-HrHMi-ll 
ICsa>CO«005030iMOOOr-H(M(M(Mr^O— i'-«OOOrHOOOIM<M?^00' 


oOTfocco<£>^050>0'<*<(MiMco-*(M^!:oTt<^oooC5->*<'^r^cec»oo— iT}<-^ooa) 


O  r-l  — I  rMOOOO 


OrlOOOOOOrH-^Olr-l— lOO 


O0'-iO0OOO-^>-iC'^!N0 


t^ooioMcoooit^csicot^aicoio-^Ti*    lOi-HXiosiooccooc^jeNt^wooit^oooj 


IMT^(NC»5<N--llOrHr-l— IOOCV3 


r^  o  CO     1  CO  CO  ro  CO  >o  — 1  ic 


CO'-^-<tiC^IMr^OCOOt^^ 


ss 


CO  3 

-1 

)iCIM»OO-^tCll0C0OTfl0C»'<*iOC000Tt<iMOOt^« 


OOOOOOOO-HOOO— (OOOOOrtO-iO 


COOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO'-iOOO'-iOOOOO'-i'-'-Hr-i-H 


a^" 


w  O 


>lC(MC35C35«Cl.-(t^Tt<eOlO 
>0'-HOCOO--HOOO 


OOOrHOO' 


00-<*i«O»O00O3»OC»00Oi>O 

r-KMrHr-lr-HOWOOOr-l 


lCSI(Nr-(C0-H'-l.-(i-lO'-lOi-ll0OC0Tt<O 


J^  3   M 


iiSi 


o  o  o    ' 


o  2  CI  _-.    looo 


2x3*^0  o^-^-^o  o^S'O-^o  S-g'^-^o  5ji2'a-^o  ajiS'a-*^o  o^-O-^o  S 
H  hJ  4^  €«■  O  H I-' -:;e  «/*  O  b-i  P  «<=►  w  O  b^  P  5*  €<?>  O  H  i-J  «^- e«i  O  H  H-^  ^  se  O  r*  H-i  «^  €^  O 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


199 


IN       ■  C^  C^l  01  r-i  r-l  (N  rl  f-i  r-(       1  i-i  rH       1  ,-(  r-1  r-< 


M  M  t^  :■»  "O 


yS§8 


„^„rt  rt  IM 


I  rH  (N  ,-;  rH  (N  rn'  r-;  ^  r-;       *      "  rH  r-J 


*"  '  53  «£  t:  r^  55  zl  •:i  *  o  M  5C  o  •>»•  (M  <N  c^ 
^  I  c>i  00  oi -^  •<»<  o  "o  o  •<»"  CO  »o  o  00  cs  cc  o 
H  ii-ti-Si-Je^i-HC^itNr-Jc^Mcvic^ieoiNi-lM 


r-;  (N       ■  .-■  rt'  (N  -H  r-<  (N  (N  eS  (H  i-H  ^  <N  r4       *  r-i  r-H  N  rt"  rt'  ,4  l-H  >-H  rH  r-H       "       '  ,-H  rH 


2  2?.  2S  ?*  3 1:  r::  Ir  "^  ■*  ^-  *  'Ci  t^  '^  f^  1^'  o 
c4  i-I  ?4  — ;  !-<■  <N  -^  r-;  (N  r-! ,-;  cvi  e^j  ci  «■  i-I  r-I  ci 


feS23§fe§^feS§:^8S22SfeS8SSS532SS88;:;gS§8fe;^SS?522SSS^?S2§feS:::2S 


!::;22:=!s■£asa£2S2:=l£^2!$2S253^S:=;2553::^22SS2Sa22SSOo■*ooNOMM<NrtC^^5Moe^lo<^^■-*^(^^c^^^■J^ 
cooccoooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooccoo 


os<--oo(^^■^oco1-HOoo^^^QC£^^>C3;5;oooQooo»oo5^t^eoc^l^^«5t^cortO:(^^^^»0(^^:c>o-HO■*»-Htoc50oc^la^ 


r^oo»ot^t^O'-i»^r--o>OT)«or^-<*'Mco-<»<Tfc^-*ai?otD-*cooccccii:^->ti 


300QO-^COr-QOt^030C?C»OCOCO-*iOOMOO 


Oi-iCOOC-IMIM      1      lOCOOO— l-Hr-,C^OO.-iOrHO-^(NOOOO 


COOOO'-I^OOrfOCOTfOC^IC^Nait- 


OCCOOOOC-^IM.-"-OIMOOOOO 


OTrt'«*<05oocoocoi-HcO'-Hioc;.-HrHcqooio«^Tt<-5t<Ns»iccooc»>raoiC<)Nai05>oiocc^-»t^«oc*;c<i-Hioict^o5co 

OWr-OO'-HC^-Hi-H.-li-l-Hrt^— li-(.-)-^i-HOi-Hrt.-lT-HOOO^OOOO^OOr-lrti-l^rHr^— (~rt^p-<i-l.-lO'-l 


ect^CCfCCqrJ^cOTJ^Ti<T»(•^l^^tO■*■*T*^esu5lOtort^cO■^TJ^T*^N1-^MCC(NTl^OTrri<'*^OCCO»00<)^M^O'9'OCC>C'*^ 


tor^cOTf— <t^LO-Ht~-     .Oico'*^3 


01   ^   r-l< 


— i(Noso;co-*cccOr-ioot 


I  CC  00       I  CO 'M  CO  •*  CO  CO  CO  CO  t^  O -^  "O  00  CO  O  ■<»<  Tt<  X 


10  O  lO 


s§s§ 


ooo     ' 


a;  o  +J  t_ ':3  o)  o  ■ 


gSSo    ;g§id 

•7-1   -fci  ^    r    =?fT-.  ,tJ  , 


<«•■=«■  O  r<  f^  «e  «^  O  H  1-^  ^  €«■  O  cr' H-*  «^  .;«■  O  H  t-' «e  «/?  O  CT"  H^' €«- e?^  O  t^  I-- 4/J  «/a  ^  H  1-^  O^  <!^  O  r^  h-' «^  «^  O  C-' r-' «/=>««■  V 


a. Si 
So. 


Sfl 


200 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


— (M.-l.-Hr-l,-(^rH.-lC^»rtC^I(NlM^ 


1-1        .  r-.  Ol  C* 


I  00  O  ■<*<  (N  IM  00  IM 


a>t^coe^o»OiOco 


co-<tit>.>Or-iT-<a>io 


3  2  2 


oooooooocoooooooooooooooo 


iio«5-«tieo":iooooo 

rO'-HCOr-ICTlCTl-^'^ 

icoTjJwiTjioiooostd 


.  O  CO  05  >— 1  »0  U5  I 


IB  a 


ft 


iiOOicO-^tDOsM-^OO 


oooo^ooooo 


28§^ 


2§?5 


o  o  o  o  o  < 


O'-l'-H'-lO^O^rH.-Hi-.-HTHrHOOOOOOOOOOO 


CO  O 


•*O(N^t-iMi-HrHOC000" 


ills 


<lj  O  -t^  tl  "^3 


g 


C3 


tec 


^te 


ilia 


9^  C.-;?^^?. 


I— ,  10  CJ  ,— 


ce  S^ 


-5^ 
^  o  p 

X3Ph 


S    o^ 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


201 


SnisipuBqo 
-jara    iBiojL 

0(N(N 

- 

oc 

esipuBqDjani 
snb9nenaosTj^[ 

-• 

'-[ 

r 

9IBS8I0qAi 

COON 

(N 

S9J0}S 

<MrH,-H 

o 

O 

S9Jo:js  uTBqo 

OOiMOOOS 

o 

§nijn?OBj 
-nuBui    iB^ox 

<N  fO  u-5  CC  CO  •-I 

CO 

2ni 
-jTHOBjnnBrri 

SnOOUBI[80SlJi\[ 

Tt<  CO  lO  (M  C^ 

<N 

-dint)8  uoi; 

-BJJOdSU'GJJ, 

«Ot^QOO-* 

ifj8UiqOBJ\[ 

—(  Tf<  ■*  CO  (N  1-1 

IN 

SIB}9tn 

snojJSjaojNi 

lco>0->i<005 

1 

^. 

I93}S  pnB  UOJI 

CO  CO  CO  «o  ^  •«*' 

^ 

-pojdSnipiina: 

lco-<s<eoco 

CO 

J9q:jB9T: 

1    Ice 

i 

CO* 

J8qqnH 

ItO 

''^ 

^. 

mnoioj^gj 

Ico 

i^ 

t^ 

siBOiraaqo 

(>1  CO  CR  O      I  OS 

^ 

Snijuud: 

CO-*«OOi-i 

<N 

J9dBJ 

CO-*  IN  CO 

■* 

jaquinq; 

I'lO     1     I 

1       »Ct-C»05Tf< 

o 

S9§BJ9A9a 

d  •  •  j  j 

• 

oooBqoj, 

IC05       lr-(l>I^ 

00 

poo^ 

OJcoeoocot-      CO 

1 
is 

=3  2 

o 

s 
§ 

> 
O 

1 

3 

'W 

S 

•<r» 

'^r^ 

K 

C3 

=c 

%> 

CO 

a 

<y 

»^ 

O 

>— r 

•* 

f^ 

^ 

d 

^. 

■^ 

5T, 

-O 

^ 

s 

^ 

<3j 

<D 

« 

Xi 

s 

^ 

CO 

W 

CO 

O 

Cft 

a 

'o' 

1 

d 

§ 

S 

o 

n 

1 

1 

M 

c 

Q 

a, 

i^i 

3 

^ 

^ 

o 

1 

^ 
> 

1 

CQ 

Cc. 

1 

^ 

B 

(M 

o 

h3 

o 

fQ 

4^ 

<i 

H 

g 

ft 

q 

snoauBnsosijv 

oc 

e<5 

9i«S9ioq,Vi 

C^i-HCO 

05 

S9J0}S 

}n9uqjBcIaa 

t^OCO 

S9Jo:js  uiBqo 

OOOCO 

-jTHOBjnuBui 
sno9nBii90sii\[ 

■^OCONCOIN 

d  --;,-;  r-;  --;  (N 

}n9radint)9 
?J0dsnBJX 

CO-*OOiCO 
^  ^  „•  ^  Cvi 

^J9niqoBj\[ 

OlMfNINcOCO 

siB:}9ni 
snoja9jno>j 

Oi 

199^8  pUB  UO.ll 

rt   Ttl  iO  t^ 

spn 
-pojdSnipiina 

00  (N  '^  O  CO 

d^^-^H-r-; 

J9q?B9T: 

Ix  t^lN 

;  r-;  ^-  Ssi 

J9qqna 

■<*<IN>0 

nin9[0Ji9(i 

d 

siB0iin9qo 

T^OOOIN 

gniiniJd: 

!i-(cot>r- 

J9dBJ 

ccSo 
d— if-! 

j9qiirnT: 

lOffl) 

S9tpX9X 

C0  00  0  00  05 

1                       I^X(M»0     1 

oooBqox   1              d   •^•^-   ; 

1                         COT^OCO      1 

S9§BJ9A9a    1                   d    ■    'rH     1 

1                              ! 

pooj 

OXMCOCOCO 

LABOR  COST  CLASSES   (PAY  ROLLS  AS  OF 
PERCENT  SALES) 

TTndpr  10 

o 

o 

o 
■* 

8 
2 

> 

o 

202 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


^ 


p 

=>-H 

t-'    1    1 

i         1 

00      ' 
(N      j 

^C0»0      1      1 

oiBseioqAV 

c^-*^oo     \     '< 

1         oscot^cc    !    ! 

^ 

!co^oi^    1 

1          ; 

ooiooo    i 

S8J0!)S  UIBtfO 

■<*  00  T-i  05  o  00  o    ' 

'          CO  IN  o;  CO  1-1 N  (N    I    ' 

1      ^-  •  -ciM^-^  : 

snoeuBiiaosiK 

C>5  00Tti(N(MvO(NO 

00               00  00  CO  00  CO  <N  CO  ■* 

Tf 

luaradmbe 
uontjijodsn^jjj 

«0  l>  t^  <»  t- CO  lO  t^  U5  CO              O 

o?cooocr^t-oct-oo 

rt^      '-' 

.^jauiqoBK 

l^lClOIMr-ITt<CO^lOO                O 

OOOSt^COCCOOOOCO 

^^ 

snojjajnojsi 

■t^-HOCS-^O       i 

o 

ir^ 

pa^s  puB  uoji 

li^-^coc^  ict^    !o 

OO  »0  CO  CO  ■*  •«*<     1 1~. 

-poad  :^uipiing: 

«o-^cocoeococo(N 

00             (N  U3  ic  CO  O  ■*  IN  «0 

N^-^^-^-  •  •  • 

00 

Jdq^wj 

t^i-iOO-*      ! 

1           (N  coocos     '     i 

wqqnn 

<N  r-;  ,h'  I 

d 

'i               0505CO 

It>.   ! 

ranaiOJ^aj             i   ' 

d    I 

I      ice 

'o 

i  !°" 

siEOiraoqo 

WOC^t-iOSOOt^O 

lo          05  ^  rM  05  «o  CO  e^  o 

Suiinuj 

0--  «5  r-l  S>1       1  IC  «D       I 

1         ^axxto    |o5^    1 

JBdEtl 

■  (M  C3  l^  O  CO      1      1 

!                      1    1 

o  -j;  05  05  CR>    j    ; 

jeqrani 

1    1    l«o    1 

1     'c 

3      i      I 
-i       1       1 

sanixaj, 

s-j  oo  o>  «o  o  t^  c^    1 

Csi  r-i  ,-:  r-i  ^"  ,-h'  ^       1 

1             OiOiM  00(M  lOTjH      1 

ooocqox 

1      ''  O  00  lO  lO      !      i 

|o 

!o50t-  CO    !    i 

CO 

sagujaAaa 

CC  -*  ^  Tt<  IC  iO      i  CD 

o 1    ' 

1    .           .    .    .    .^    .    1    . 

"* 

1         cc  o  CO  .-H  00  o3 --1  o  lO  lo          a 

MCOCOOOOt^'*'-*'^ 

poo^ 

'"""'^^        M^ 

t-H  T-1  i-H          T-(  CO 

o 

2 
1 

P4 

«  'i 

■<    ' 

l\ 

^   1 

^  ; 

1  u- 

fit 

5  c 

122. 

i  i  « 
•  i  s 

1   ',     f^ 

.    1      o 

i  ';    £ 

lu5      1 

o  c 

I 


INDEX 


ABOVE  GROUND  CONSTRUCTION:  Page 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 180 

AGRICULTURAL  COOPERATIVES  22 

ACCOUNTING  PERIOD,  DEFINITION  OF 36-38,  74,  87,  117 

AFFILIATION,  DEFINITION  0F_  42-45 

AGRICULTURAL  MACHINERY: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables _____         __  179 

Text 179 

ALCOHOLIC  BEVERAGES  (WHOLESALE): 

Charts 98,  110 

Tables 106,  200 

Also  see  Beverages. 

AIRPLANES: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

AIR  TRANSPORTATION: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 180 

AMORTIZATION 121 

Also  see  Depreciation. 

ASSESSMENT  OF  PROPERTY 110 

AMUSEMENTS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

ANTHRACITE  COAL: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

APPAREL  (RETAIL) : 

Charts 98,  110 

Tables 195 

Also  see  Clothing. 

AUTO  PARTS: 

Retail 106,196 

Wholesale 106,  199 

AUTO  DEALERS 196 

AUTOBUS: 

Charts 62,71.86 

Tables 180 

AUTOMOBILES: 

Manufacturing 106,  192 

See  Motor  vehicles. 
Retail: 

Charts 98,110 

Tables 196 

BAD  DEBTS  (STATUTORY  DEDUCTION  0F)___   13-15,  29,  33,  150,  152,  155 

BAKING  AND  CONFECTIONERY: 
Manufacturing: 

Charts_._ 62,  71,  86 

Tables 106,  178,  188 

Text  98 

RetaiL:_::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 106,193 

Wholesale... 106,  198 

203 


204  INDEX 

BANKING:  T-age 

Tables 180 

Text 59,73,86 

See  National  banks,  State  banks,  joint-stock  land  banks. 

BANKING  AFFILIATES,  EXEMPTION  OF 75 

BANKRUPT   CORPORATIONS,  EXEMPTION  OF 23,73 

BENEVOLENT  INSURANCE  ASSOCIATIONS,  EXEMPTIONS  0F_         22 

BERLE,  A.  A 7 

BEVERAGES  (MANUFACTURING): 

Charts 24, 

30,  32,  35,  38,  47,  49,  51,  56,  61,  62,  71,  77,  86,  88,  89,  93,  94,  99, 
100,  101,  110. 

Tables 103,  106,  112, 

113,  125,  141,  142,  150,  154-160,  162-165,  167,  174,  178,  186,  188. 

Text 31,  38,  46,  49,  59,  78,  89,  98,  101,  102 

BITUMINOUS  COAL  MINING: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 179 

BLAKEY,  ROY 24,  92 

BOECKEL,  R.  M 123 

BONBRIGHT,  JAMES 39,40 

BONE  PRODUCTS: 

Charts 62,  71,86 

Tables 179 

BRANDEIS,  JUSTICE 34 

BOOKS  (RETAIL) 107,  197 

BREWERIES 106,  189 

BUILDING  AND  LOAN  ASSOCIATIONS,  EXEMPTIONS  OF 21 

BUILDING  PRODUCTS  AND  MATERIALS: 
Manufacturing: 

Charts 88,  89,  93,  94,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables,: 104,  112,  113,  141,  142 

Text 89,  95,  98 

Also  see  Stone,  clay,  and  glass. 

Retail 196 

"BURDEN"  OF  TAXES 2,  4,  81 

BUREAU  OF  INTERNAL  REVENUE 41-45,134-136 

BUSINESS  CYCLES,  SENSITIVITY  OF  INCOME  TAXES  T0-_  9,13,82 

BUSINESS  LEAGUES,  EXEMPTION  OF 22 

BUSINESS  PRIVILEGE  TAXES 110-114 

BUSINESS  SERVICE: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

See  Service. 
CANNING: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 188,  178,  106 

Text 102 

See  Food. 

CAPITAL  LOSS,  DEDUCTION  OF 13-15,29,33,150,153,157 

CAPITAL  STRUCTURE,  EFFECT  OF  TAXES  ON 73-74,91-195 

CARPETS: 

Charts 62,  71,86 

Tables 178 

See  Textiles. 
CARTAGE  AND  STORAGE: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 180 

See  Public  utilities. 

CASH  DIVIDENDS 149,  178-182 

CELLULOID  PRODUCTS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

See  Leather. 
CEMETERY  CORPORATIONS,  EXEMPTION  0F__. 22 


INDEX  205 

CHAIN  STORES:  Page 

Charts 88,  89,  93,  94,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 104,  107,  112,  113,  141,  142 

Text 89 

CHARITABLE  CORPORATIONS,  EXEMPTION  OF  22 

CHEMICALS: 

Charts 24,  30,  32,  35, 

38,  47,  49,  51,  56,  62,  71,  77,  86,  88,  89,  93,  94,  98,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 104,  1 12, 

113,  125,  141,  142,  150,  154-160,  162-165,  170,  176,  179,  191,  205 

CHINA  TRADE  ACT  CORPORATIONS 23  73 

CIVIC  LEAGUES,  EXEMPTION  OF '22 

CLAY  PRODUCTS: 

Charts 62,  71,86 

Tables 179,  106,  191 

See  Stone,  clay,  and  glass. 

CLOTHING: 

Manufacturing: 

Charts 30,  32,  35,  61,  62,  71,  77,  86 

Tables 106,  175,  178,  189,  204 

Text 31,59,78 

See  also  Textiles. 
Retail 106,  107,  195 

COAL  AND  OTHER  FUEL  (RETAIL):  Tables 197,106 

COAL  MINING: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179,  125 

COLM,  GERHARD 74 

COMMISSION  (WHOLESALE): 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

CONFECTIONERY  PRODUCTS: 
Manufacturing: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 106,  178,  188 

Text 98 

Wholesale 106,  198 

Retail 106,  193 

CONSENT  DIVIDENDS 74 

CONSOLIDATED  TAX  RETURNS: 

Advantages  of_ 48-52 

Origin  of 41-45 

Repeal  of 44-45,  49-51 

Tables 159-163 

Also  see  Holding  companies. 

CONSTRUCTION  (MANUFACTURING): 

Charts 24,  30,  32,  35,  38,  47,  49.  51,  56,  60,  71,  77,  62,  86 

Tables 125,  150-153,  158-161,  163-165,  172-173,  177,  180,  205 

Text 24,  25,  30,  31,  33,  35,  37,  38,  46,  49,  59,  70,  78,  101 

CONSTRUCTION  SUPPLIES  (WHOLESALE): 

Charts 98,110 

Tables 198 

CONSUMPTION  TAXES 101-107 

Also  see  General  sales,  liquor,  and  tobacco  taxes. 

CONTRIBUTIONS  (STATUTORY  DEDUCTION  OF) 13 

COOPERATIVES,  EXEMPTION  OF— 

Agriculture 22 

Banks 21 

Ditch 22 

Insurance 22 

Irrigation 22 

Marketing 22 

Purchasing 22 

Telephone --         22 

CORPORATE  SAVINGS,  EFFECT  OF  TAXES  ON 73-74,82-86 


206  INDEX 

CORPORATIONS:  Pa^e 

N  umber  of 134 

Entity 39-41 

COSMETICS  (RETAIL) 197 

COST  OF  GOODS  SOLD  (STATUTORY  DEDUCTION  OF) 13-16, 

28-30,  150,  151,  154 

COST  OF  OPERATIONS  (STATUTORY  DEDUCTION  OF) 13-16, 

28-30,  150,  151,  154 

COTTON: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 178 

CREAMERIES  AND  DAIRIES: 

Tables 188,  106 

Text 98 

CREDITOR  CAPITAL,  EFFECT  OF  TAXES  ON 91-95 

Also  see  Interest  paid, 

CREDITS  UNDER  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAX: 

Dividends  paid  out 75 

Dividends  received 54-56 

Interest  received  on  Government  securities 63-64 

Minimum  amount  of  net  income 23-25 

Prior  years'  loss 36-38 

CUSTOMS 5-6 

DAIRY  AND  POULTRY  (WHOLESALE) 106,198 

DEBT,  RETIREMENT  OF 74 

Also  see  Undistributed  profits  tax. 

"DEBT  RIDDEN"  CORPORATIONS 74,95 

DEDUCTIONS  FROM  GROSS  INCOME 13-17,28-36,150-159 

Also  see  Contributions  or  gifts,  cost  of  goods  sold,  cost  of  operations, 
depletion,  depreciation,  interest  paid,  net  losses  for  prior  years, 
officers,  compensation  of,  rent,  repairs,  taxes  paid. 

DEPARTMENT  STORES: 

Charts 88,  89,  93,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 104,  106,  112,  113,  141,  142,  194 

Text 189 

DEPLETION  (STATUTORY  DEDUCTION  OF) 16, 

30-31,  149,  150,  153,  156-157,  181-182 

DEPRECIATION  (STATUTORY  DEDUCTION) 16, 

30-31,  149,  150,  152,  156,  181-182 
Also  see  Amortization. 

DEPRESSION,  EFFECT  ON   TAXES 13,82,105 

DESIDERATA  OF  A  ''GOOD"  TAX  SYSTEM 116 

DISTILLERIES 106,  189 

DIVIDEND  DISTRIBUTION,  TYPES  OF 76-77 

DIVIDENDS  PAID  OUT: 

Magnitude  of 17-19,39-40,76-79,84 

Also  see  Undistributed-profits  tax. 

DOMESTIC  SERVICE: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

Text 97n 

DOUBLE  TAXATION 53-56 

Also  see  Intercorporate  dividends. 

DOYLE  V.  MITCHELL  BROS.  CO 31n 

DRUGS: 

DRUGS  AND  COSMETICS  (RETAIL): 

Charts 98,  110 

Tables 106 

DRY  GOODS: 

Wholesale 106,200 

Retail 194 

DUN  &  BRADSTREET  TAX  BURDEN  SURVEY 98, 

102-103,  105-107,  110,  136,  143-144 

Manufacturing 106,  191 

Wholesale 106,  199 

Retail 98,  106,  110,  197 

EISNER  y.  MACOMBER 75 


INDEX 


207 


Page 

EMPLOYEES'  ASSOCIATIONS,  EXEMPTION  OF  22 

EMPLOYMENT,  EFFECT  OF  TAXES  ON  97-101 

ENTREPRENEURIAL  LABOR,  EXEMPTION 'OF  98 

EQUITY  CAPITAL q1_95 

EQUITY  RATIO,  DEFINED ".."."I""'.'.!""""""        140 

Tables 183-185,  187 

ESCH,  CONGRESSMAN '    53 

EXCESS-PROFITS  TAX """'  10-12 

27,  67-70,  81-86,  88,  92,  121-125,  12"&-"l29",  149,  178-181 

EXEMPTIONS __.._.  21-23 

Also  see  specific  industries. 

EXPENDITURES,  GOVERNMENTAL 4 

ELECTRIC  LIGHT  AND  POWER: 

Charts 62,  71,86 

Tables 125,  180 

Text 59,86 

ELECTRIC  RAILROADS: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 125,  180 

ELECTRICAL  GOODS  (WHOLESALE) 106,  199 

ELECTRICAL  MACHINERY: 

Charts 67,71,86 

Tables 106,  179,  192 

Text 102 

ENGINES 106,  193 

EFFECTIVE  TAX  RATES 10-11,24-25,57 

FACTORY  MACHINERY: 

Charts 62-71,86 

Tables-      _   _       179 

FAMILY  CLOTmNG"(RETAYLy_\\"^^^'^"""'"" 

FARM  IMPLEMENTS  (RETAIL) 107,194,196 

FARMERS'  SUPPLIES  (RETAIL): 

Charts 98,  110 

Tables 106,  193,  194 

FEDERAL  CAPITAL  STOCK  TAX 67-70,88,92,126-129,184,186-187 

Also  see  Excess-profits  tax. 

FEDERAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAXES 149,163-200 

History  of 9-12 

FEDERAL  EXCISES 101-104,  188-200 

FERTILIZERS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

FETTER,  PROFESSOR 41 

FILLING  STATIONS: 

Charts 98,110 

Tables 106,197 

FINANCE: 

Charts 24,  30,  32,  35,  38,  47,  49,  51,  56,  60,  71,  77 

Tables 125,  150-153,  158-161,  163-1^65,  173,  177,  180,207 

Text 24,  25,  31,  33,  35,  37,  38,  46,  49,  51,  59,  65,  78 

FISH: 

Wholesale 106,  198 

Retail 106,193 

FIXED-COST  TAXES 2,  109-114 

FLINT  V.  STONE  TRACY 9n,  63 

FLOOR  COVERINGS  (RETAIL) 19o 

FLORISTS  (RETAIL) ^  106 

FLOUR  AND  FEED  MILLING 106,188 

See  Mill  products.  ^^  ^^  ^, 

FLUCTUATING  ENTERPRISE 21,36-38,68-70,74 

FOOD: 

''™SSr£^ 24,30,32.35  38  47 

49,  51,  56,  61,  62,  71,  77,  86,  88,  89,  93,  94,  98,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables     ^^'^' 

"ii2,"ii3,'i25."i4i,"i42,  150,  154-160,  162-166,  174,  178,  188.  203 
Text ______-_- 38,  46,  49,  51,  59,  78,  98 


208  IISDEX 

FOOD— Continued. 

Wholesale:  Page 

Charts 98,  110 

Tables 198 

Retail: 

Charts 98,  110 

Tables 193 

FOREIGN  CORPORATIONS 73 

FOREST  PRODUCTS: 

Charts 24,30,32,35,38,47, 

49,  51,  56,  61,  62,  71,  77.  86,  88,  89,  93,  94,  98,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 103,  106,  125,  150,  154-160,  162-165,  169,  175,  179,  189,  190,  204 

Text  24,  30,  31,  38,  46,  49,  59.  70,  78 

FOUNDRIES 106,  192 

FRANK,  JEROME 91 

FRATERNAL  ORGANIZATIONS,  EXEMPTIONS  OF 22 

FRIDAY,  DAVID 124 

FRUIT  (WHOLESALE) 106,  198 

FURNITURE: 

Manufacturing: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 106,  179,  190 

Retail : 

Charts 98,  110 

Tables 106,  195 

GALVESTON  ELECTRIC  CO.  v.   GALVESTON 3 

GAS  (MINING): 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 125,  179 

GAS  (UTILITIES): 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 125,  180 

Text 86 

GENERAL  MERCHANDISE: 

Charts 98,  110 

Tables 106,  194 

GEORGE,  EDWIN  B 73n,  77n 

GLASS,  CARTER 123 

GLASS  PRODUCTS 196 

See  Stone,  clav,  and  glass. 

GOVERNMENT  INTEREST 13-15,  63-65 

GOVERNMENT  REGULATION  OF  PRICE:  Income  taxes  under 3 

GRADUATION  OF  RATES 12,25-27 

GROCERIES: 

Wholesale 106,  198 

Retail 106,  193 

GROCERIES  AND  MEATS 106,107 

GROSS  INCOME 149 

GROSS  MARGIN,  DEFINED 140 

HARDWARE: 

Manufacturing: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 106,  179,  192 

Wholesale 106,  199 

Retail 106,  107,  195,  196 

HEATING  SUPPLIES  (WHOLESALE) 106,199 

HEER,  CLARENCE 4 

HELVERING,  COMMISSIONER 72 

HIGHWAY  TAXES 5-6 

HOLDING  COMPANY 39-41 

Also  ?ee  Consolidated  returns. 

HOSIERY 106,189 

HOUSE  WAYS  AND  MEANS  COMMITTEE 23,45,130 

HOUSEHOLD  APPLIANCES  (RETAIL) 106,195 

HOUSEHOLD  MACHINERY: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 


INDEX  209 

Page 

HOUSTON,  SECRETARY loq 

HOWE,  F.  C 9 

HUGHES  V.  COMMISSIONER 36 

HULL,  CORDELL 54 

ICE  MANUFACTURING io6  188 

INCIDENCE  OF  TAXES 2-3' 107 

INCOME  TAX,  SHIFTING  OF '      3 

INCOME  TAX  ACTS  OF— 

1894 9 

1909 9-16,  23,  25,  34,  .53,  92 

1913 10,23,34,54,92 

1916 10,54,92 

1917 10,  23,  25,  54-55,  87,  121 

1918 10,  23,  25,  31,  37,  42,  55,  87,  92,  121-124 

1921 1 0,  23,  34,  37,  42-43 

1924 10,25,43 

1926 11 

1928 11,23,43 

1932 10-11,23,25,44,92 

1933 11,67 

1934 11,44-45,55,92 

1935 11-12,25-27 

1936 11-12,  26,  27,  35,  55,  70-74,  89 

1937 11 

1938 11-12,  27,  45n,  67.  74,  89 

1939 11-12,  27,  37,  45n 

1940  (I) 11 

1940  (II) 11-12,55 

INDEPENDENT  RETAILER 107 

INDIVIDUAL  INCOME  TAX 25,73 

INDUSTRIAL  CHEMICALS 106,  191 

See  Chemicals. 

INDUSTRIAL  UNIT  OF  TAXATION 39,52 

Also  see  Consolidated  returns. 

INSTRUMENTS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

INSURANCE: 

Charts 62,71 

Tables 180 

Text 22,53,59,73,86 

See  Life  insurance. 

INTERCORPORATE  AFFILIATION 39-45 

Also  see  Consolidated  returns. 

INTERCORPORATE  DIVIDENDS 53-63 

Also  see  Consolidated  returns. 

INTEREST  PAID  (STATUTORY  DEDUCTION  OF) 13-16, 

30,  149,  150,  152,  155 
Also  see  Creditor  capital. 

^'INVESTED  CAPITAL" 121-122 

Also  see  Excess  profits. 

INVESTMENT,  EFFECT  OF  TAXES  ON 17-19,81-86 

Also  see  Reinvestment. 

invp:stment  trusts 59 

Dividends  received  and  paid 55 

IRON  AND  STEEL: 

Charts 62,  71,  86,  88,  89,  93,  94,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables   _    104,106,112,113,141,142,179,191 

Text 89 

IVORY  PRODUCTS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

JACKSON,  ROBERT 25,  26,  45n 

JEWELRY  (RETAIL) 106,  197 

JOINT  COMMITTEE  ON  INTERNAL  REVENUE  TAXATION 43 


210  INDEX 

JOINT-STOCK  LAND  BANKS:  Page 

Charts 62,71 

Exemption  of 22 

Tables 180 

Text 73 

KITCHINS,  SENATOR 55 

KNIT  GOODS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 178 

KOSHLAND  v.  HELVERING 76 

LABOR  COST  RATIO 140 

LABOR  ORGANIZATIONS,  EXEMPTION  OF 21 

LARGE  CORPORATIONS.  26,  30-31,  48-49,  53-54,  68-70,  78,  81-86,  89,  98,  110 

LEATHER: 

Charts   24,  30,  32,  35,  38,  47, 

49,  51,  56,  61,  62,  71,  77,  86,  88,  89,  93,  94,  98,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 104,112, 

113,  125,  141,  142,  150,  154-160,  162-165,  168,  175,  178,  189,  204 
Text 31,38,46,49,59,78 

LENROOT,  SENATOR 55 

LIFE  INSURANCE: 

Special  deduction  legislation 34,  35 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 180 

LIGNITE  (MINING): 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

LIQUOR  TAXES 102 

Also  see  Alcoholic  beverages. 

LOAN  COMPANIES: 

Charts 67,71,86 

Tables 180 

LOSSES 13,34 

Fire,  Storm,  Shipwreck,  Casualty,  Theft. 
Also  see  Net  loss. 

LUMBER: 

Manufacturing: 

Charts HO 

Tables 103,  106,  112,  113,  141,  142,  190 

See  Forest  products. 

Wholesale 106,  199 

RetaiL         98.  106,  110,  195,  196 

MACHINE  SHOPS 106,  192 

MACHINERY: 

Charts 62,  71,  86,  88,  89,  93,  94,  98,  99,  100.  101,  110 

Tables 104,  106,  112,  113,  141,  142,  179,  192 

Text 89,98 

MACHINERY  AND  EQUIPMENT  (WHOLESALE) 106,199 

MAGILL,  ROSWELL 13 

MAIL-ORDER  HOUSES 106 

MANUFACTURING: 

Charts-  24,  30,  32,  35,  38,  47,  49,  51,  56,  60,  71,  77,  88,  93,  94,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 104,  106,  112,  113,  125,  132,  133,  141,  142,  150-166,  174,  203 

Text 24,  25,  30,  31,  33,  35,  37,  38,  46,  49,  50,  51,  59,  65,  78,  95,  101 

McREYNOLDS,  JUSTICE... 34 

MEANS,  GARDINER  C 7,40 

MEAT  PACKING 106,  188 

See  Packing-house  products. 

MEATS  (RETAIL) 193 

MEATS  AND  FISH: 

Wholesale 106,  198 

Retail 106,193 

MECHANIZATION 98-101 

Also  see  Pav-roll  taxes. 

MEN'S  AND  BOYS'  CLOTHING 107,195 

See  Clothing. 


INDEX  211 

METAL  BUILDING  MATERIALS  AND  SUPPLIES-  Page 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables _        __        __  ,70 

METAL  MINING:  ^^^ 

Charts 62,71,86 

lables I9f^   17Q 

METALS:  i^o,  i/y 

Charts 24,  30,  32,  35,  38,  47,  49,  51,  56,  62,  71,  77,  86,  98  110 

Tables 125,  150,  154-160,  162-165,  171,  176,  179,  191,  192  205 

METaIs,- PRECIOUS-: ^''  ''■  '''  ''■  «•  ''•  ''•  ^« 

?abreL-:::::::::::::::::::::::-.::::: ''-''-.f, 

MILK  DEALERS joo 

MILL  PRODUCTS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 170 

Text :_:::::::: 98 

MILLS,  OGDEN o% 

MINING: 

Charts 24,  30,  32,  35,  38,  47,  49,  51,  56,  60,  71,  77 

Tables 125,  150-153,  158-161,  163-165,  171,  177,  206 

Text _ 24,  25,  30,  31,  33,  35,  37,  38,  46,  49,  50,  59,  78 

MINIMUM  NET  INCOME,  EXEMPTION  OF 123-25,150 

Also  see  Small  business. 

MONOPOLY  PROFITS 87-90 

Also  see  Excess-profits  tax. 

MOTION-PICTURE  PRODUCERS: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables ___   ___  179 

Text ::::     79 

MOTION-PICTURE  THEATERS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables ^ 179 

MOTOR-VEHICLE  DEALERS ./....'.       106 

See  Auto  parts. 
MOTOR  VEHICLES: 

Charts 30,  32,  35,  62,  71,  77,  86 

Tables 106,  177,  179,  192,  206 

Text 59,  78,  102 

See  Metals. 
MUTUAL-INVESTMENT  COMPANIES: 

Dividend  credit  of 55 

MUTUAL  SAVINGS  BANKS,  EXEMPTION  OF...  21 

NATIONAL  BANKS: 

Charts . 62,  71,  86 

Tables 180 

NATIONAL  INDUSTRIAL  CONFERENCE  BOARD 9n,  111-113 

NATIONAL  INDUSTRIAL  RECOVERY  ACT 67 

NATIONAL  LIFE  INSURANCE  CO.  v.  UNITED  STATES 34 

NATIONAL  MORTGAGE  ASSOCIATIONS,  EXEMPTION  0F__     _         75 
NET  LOSS  FOR  PRIOR  YEARS  (STATUTORY  DEDUCTION  0F)_  36-38 

NEWLANDS,  SENATOR 53-54 

NEWSPAPERS 106,  190 

NONALCOHOLIC  BEVERAGES: 

Charts 62,  71,86 

Tables 178,  189 

Text 98 

See  Beverages. 
NONFERROUS  METALS: 

Charts 88,  89,  93,  94,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 104,  106,  112,  113,  141,  142,  192 

Text 98 

NORMAL  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAX:  Tables 83,  165,  174,  186-187 

^'NORMAL  RETURN'' 121 

See  Excess-profits  tax. 


212  INDEX 

Page; 

NURSERIES  AND  FLORISTS  (RETAIL)   197 

OCEAN  AND  COASTAL  TRANSPORT 125 

OFFICE  EQUIPMENT: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

OFFICERS,    COMPENSATION    OF    (STATUTORY    DEDUCTION 

OF) 13-15,33,  150,  151,  154-155 

OIL  AND  GAS  (MINING): 

Charts 62,  71,86 

Tables 1 79 

OLIPHANT,  HERMAN 72n,  130-131 

PACKING-HOUSE  PRODUCTS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 106,  178,  188 

Text 98 

See  Meats. 
PAINTS: 

Manufacturing: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 106,  179,  191 

Wholesale 106,  199 

Retail 106,  196 

PAPER: 

Manufacturing: 

Charts 24,  30,  32,  35, 

38,  47,  49,  51,  66,  62,  71,  77,  86,  88,  89,  93,  94,  98,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 103,  106,  112, 

113,  125,  141,  142,  150,  154-160,  162-165,  169,  175,  179,  190,  204 

Text 30,31,38,46,49,59,78,95 

Wholesale  _  . 106,  200 

PAYNE,  CONGRESSMAN 53 

PAY-ROLL  TAXES 97-101 

Regressive '      101 

Mechanization 98-100 

Tables 1 88-202 

PEAT  (MINING): 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

PERIODICALS 190 

PETROLEUM: 

Manufacturing: 

Charts 30, 

32,  35,  62,  71,  77,  86.  88,  89,  93,  94,  98,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 104,  106,  112,  113,  141,  142,  176,  178,  191,  205 

Text 31,59,78,  102 

See  Chemicals. 
Wholesale : 

Charts 98,  110 

Tables 106,  200 

Retail,  see  Filling  stations. 
PIPE  LINES: 

Charts 62,  7 1 ,  86 

Tables 180 

PLANING-MILL  PRODUCTS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

PLUMBING  AND  HEATING  SUPPLIES  (WHOLESALE) 106,199 

POLLOCK  V.  FARMERS'  LOAN  &  TRUST  CO 9n 

POULTRY  (WHOLESALE) 106,  198 

PRICES 2-3,97,  101-110 

PRINTING  AND  PUBLISHING: 

Charts 24,30,32,35, 

38,  47,  49,  51,  56,  62,  71,  77,  86,  88,  89,  93,  94,  98,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 104,  106, 

112,  113,  125,  141,  142,  150,  154-160,  162-165,  170,  176,  190,  205 
Text 24,  30,  31,  38,  46,  49,  59,  78,  101 


INDEX 


213 


Pag€ 

PRIOR  YEARS'  LOSSES 36-38,158-159 

See  Fluctuating  enterprise,  small  corporations. 

PRODUCE  AND  FRUIT  (WHOLESALE) 106  198 

PROFESSIONAL  SERVICE: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables _     _      179 

PROFIT   RATIO,   DEFINED ....[.  140 

Tables 90,  i  83- 187 

PROFITS,  CORPORATE I49,  181-182 

Definition  for  tax  purposes 13-17 

Effect  of  taxes  on _     17-19  81-86 

PROGRESSIVE  TAX  RATES 12  25-27  57 

PROPERTY  TAXES 109-110,188-200,202 

PUBLIC  UTILITIES: 

Charts 24,  30,  32,  35,  38,  47,  49,  51,  56,  60,  62,  71,  77,  86 

Tables 125,  150-153,  158-161,  163-165,  173,  177,  207 

Text 24,  25,  30,  31,  33,  35,  37,  38,  46,  49,  50,  59,  78,  101 

PUBLISHING.     See  Printing. 

RADIO  AND  HOUSEHOLD  APPLIANCES  (RETAIL) 106,195 

RADIOS  (MANUFACTURING): 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

Text 79 

RADIOBROADCASTING: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 180 

RAILROAD  EQUIPMENT: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

RAILROADS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 125,  180 

Text 45,53,54,59 

RATHENAU,  WALTER 7 

RAYON  PRODUCTS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 178 

REAL  ESTATE: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 180 

RECEIPTS,  PUBLIC 4-6 

REGRESSION,  DEFERRED 69n 

REINVESTMENT  OF  PROFITS 17-18,70-79,81-86,181-182 

RENT  PAID  (STATUTORY  DEDUCTION  OF) 13-15,33,150,151,155 

REPAIRS  (STATUTORY  DEDUCTION  OF) 34 

RESTAURANTS: 

Charts 98,  110 

Tables 107,  197 

RETAIL: 

Charts 62,71,86,98,110 

Tables 179,193 

ROOSEVELT,  F.  D 1,26 

ROOT,  ELIHU 23 

RUBBER: 

Charts 24,  30,  32,  35,  38, 

47,  49,  51,  56,  61,  62,  71,  77,  86,  88,  89,  93,  94,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 104,  112,  113, 

125,  141,  142,  150,  154-160,  162-165,  168-169,  175,  179,  204 
Text 31,  38,  46,  49,  51,  59,  70,  78,  89 

SAWMILL  AND  PLANING-MILL  PRODUCTS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

SCHMIDT,  O.  A 68n,  126-127 

SECOND-HAND  STORES 197 

SECURITIES  AND  EXCHANGE  COMMISSION 136-140 

SENATE  FINANCE  COMMITTEE 42 

262698— 41— No.  9 15 


214  INDEX 

SERVICE:  Page 

Charts 24,  30,  32,  35,  38,  47,  49,  51,  56,  60,  62,  71,  77,  86 

Tables 125,  150-153,  158-161,  163-165,  172,  177,  206 

Text 24,  30,  31,  33,  35,  38,  46,  49,  51,  59,  78 

SHIFTING 2-3 

See  also  Incidence. 

SHIPBUILDING: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 180 

Text 79,  97n 

SHOES: 

Manufacturing: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 106,  1 79 

Text 86 

Retail 106,  195 

SILK  AND  RAYON: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 178 

Text 86 

SILVERHERZ,  JOSEPH  D llOn 

SIZE  OF  ENTERPRISE: 

Charts.  _.  24,  30,  32,  35,  38,  58,  60,  61,  62,  69,  71,  77,  83,  85,  88,  92,  98,  99,  110 

Tables 49,  128-129,  132-133, 

142,  150-157,  159,  165-178,  181-185,  188-201,  203-207 
Text-  21-24,  27,  30-36,  38,  57-61,  65,  68-70,  77-79,  81-86,  89,  92,  98,  109,  110 

SMALL  BUSINESS 23-27,  33,  36,  38,  68-70,  74.  78,  81-86,  92,  98,  110 

Also  see  Graduation,  minimum  income,  progression. 

SPECIFIC  CREDITS  IN  DOLLARS 23-25 

Also  see  Minimum  net  income. 

SPRECKELS  SUGAR  REFINING  CO.  v.  McCLAIN 9n 

STATE    CORPORATE   FRANCHISE   TAXES    (OTHER   THAN   ON 

INCOME) 110-114 

STATE  CORPORATE  INCOME  TAXES 9n,  12n,  113-114,  188-200 

STATE     CORPORATION     ORGANIZATION     AND     ENTRANCE 

TAXES .  _         110-111 

STATE  SALES  TAXES 105-107,188-200 

STATE  AND  PRIVATE  BANKS: 

Charts 62,  7 1,  86 

Tables  180 

STATIONERY"(REfAIL)Vrri'^]]]]]]"]";"]]^  197 

STEAM  RAILROADS: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 1 25,  180 

STEEL: 

Charts 62,71,86,88,89,93,94,99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 104,  106,  112,  113,  141,  142,  179,  191 

Text 89 

STOCK  DIVIDEND,  TAXABILITY  OF 75-76 

STOCK  AND  BOND  BROKERS: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 180 

STOCKHOLDERS: 

Control  of  corporation 6-7 

STONE,  CLAY,  AND  GLASS: 

Charts 24,30,32,35,38,47,49,51,56,62,71,77,86,98,  110 

Tables 106,  125,  150,  154-160,  162-165,  170-171,  176,  179,  191,  205 

Text 24,  3 1 ,  38,  46,  49,  59,  70,  78 

See  Building  products. 

STORAGE: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 180 

STRATTON'S  INDEPENDENT  LTD.  v.  H A WBERT 31n 

SUGAR: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 178 

Text _    _        ___    59,86 


INDEX  215 

Page 

TAFT,  WILLIAM 9_10 

TAXABLE  INCOME,  CONCEPT  OF 13 

TAX  COLLECTIONS 4-6  146-147 

"TAX  CORRECTIVES" _  '  i 

TAX  RATIOS: 

Capital  stock  tax 184 

Corporate  taxes 188,  200 

Excess  profits  tax 178-180,  183 

Income  tax 163-173,  188-200 

Normal  tax 165,  174-180,  183 

Pay  roll  taxes 188,  200 

Property  taxes 188,  200 

Sales  taxes 188,  200 

Undistributed  profits  tax 178-180,  185 

TAXES,  TYPES  OF 2-3 

TAXES  PAID  (STATUTORY   DEDUCTION  0F)__.   13-15,31,150.152,156 
TAX-EXEMPT   SECURITIES: 

Distribution  of 64 

Income  received  from 63-65 

TAXING  POWER 115 

TAX  RATES,  STATUTORY 10-12 

TAX  SOURCES,  CHANGING : 5-6,148 

TEACHERS'  RETIREMENT  FUND  ASSOCIATIONS,  EXEMPTION 

OF 22 

TELEPHONE  AND  TELEGRAPH: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 125,  180 

Text 79,  86 

TERMINALS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 180 

TEXTILE  WEAVING 106,  189 

TEXTILES: 

Charts 24,  30,  32,  35, 

38,  47,  49,  51,  56,  61,  71,  77,  88,  89,  93,  94,  98,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 103,  112,  113, 

125,  141,  142,  150,  154-160,  162-165,  168,  174,  178,  189,  203 

Text 24,  38,  46,  49,  59,  89,  98 

THEATERS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

THORP,  W.  L xi,  73n,  77n 

TIRES  AND  TUBES: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

TOBACCO: 

Manufacturing : 

Charts 24,30,32,35, 

38,  47,  49,  51,  56,  61,  71,  77,  88,  89,  93,  94,  98,  99,  100,  101,  110,  203 

Tables_..___._-_-_______-_  — 103,  112,  113, 

125,  141,  142,  150,  154-160,  162-165,  167,  174,  178,  188,  189 

Text 31,  38,  46,  49,  51,  59,  70,  78,  89,  101,  102 

Wholesale 66,  71,  86,  198 

TOOLS: 

Charts 62,71,86 

Tables 179 

TRADE" 

Charts  __     24,30,32,35, 

38,  47,  49,  51,  56,  60,  71,  77,  88,  89,  93,  94,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables  104,  125,  150-153,  158-161,  163-165,  172,  177,  179,  206 

Text  24,  25,  30,  31,  33,  35.  38,  46,  49,  51,  78 

TRANSPORTATION:  ^„  ^^   „^ 

Charts  62,71,86 

Tables 180 

See  Publications. 


215  INDEX 

TRANSPORTATION  EQUIPMENT:  Page 

Charts 88,  89,  93,  94,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 104,  106,  112,  113,  141,  142 

Text 89,95.98,  152 

TROXEL,  C.  E 3n 

UNDERGROUND  AND  SURFACE  CONSTRUCTION; 

Charts 62,  71,86 

Tables 180 

UNDISTRIBUTED  PROFITS  TAX 70-79,149 

Equity  ratio  comparison 95,  185,  187 

Industry  comparison 79,  178-181 

Profit  rate  comparison 89-90,  185-186 

Size  comparison 77-78 

VARIABLE-COST  TAXES 21,  97-107 

See  also  Pay-roil  taxes,  Federal  excises,  and  State  sales  taxes. 

VARIETY  STORES 106,  194 

VARNISHES  (WHOLESALE) 106,  199 

WALLPAPER  (RETAIL) 196 

WAR:  Effect  of 4d,  13 

WAR  PROFITS  TAX 121-125.149 

WATER  (UTILITIES): 

Charts 62,  71,86 

Tables 180 

WATER  TRANSPORTATION: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 180 

WHISKY  TAX 102 

WHOLESALE: 

Charts 62,  71,  86,  88,  89,  93,  94,  98,  99,  100,  101,  110 

Tables 104,  106,  112,  113,  141,  142,  179 

WINERIES-- 189 

WOMEN'S  WEAR  (RETAIL) 106,195 

WOOLEN  AND  WORSTED  PRODUCTS: 

Charts 62,  71,  86 

Tables 178