Skip to main content

Full text of "Investigation of concentration of economic power; monograph no. 1[-43]"

See other formats


Northeastern  University 


2SS^SS3SSSSSSS 


School  of  Law 
Library 


^^3d  Se°8sfon^^}        SENATE  COMMITTEE  PRINT 


INVESTIGATION  OF  CONCENTRATION 
OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


TEMPORARY  NATIONAL  ECONOMIC 
COMMITTEE 

A     STUDY     MADE     UNDER     THE     AUSPICES     OF     THE 
TREASURY     DEPARTMENT     FOR     THE      TEMPORARY 
NATIONAL    ECONOMIC    COMMITTEE,    SEVENTY-SIXTH 
CONGRESS,    THIRD    SESSION,    PURSUANT    TO    PUBLIC 
RESOLUTION     NO.     113     (SEVENTY-FIFTH     CONGRESS), 
AUTHORIZING  AND  DIRECTING  A  SELECT  COMMITTEE 
TO  MAKE  A  FULL  AND  COMPLETE  STUDY  AND  INVES- 
TIGATION  WITH   RESPECT   TO   THE   CONCENTRATION 
OF    ECONOMIC    POWER    IN,    AND    FINANCIAL 
CONTROL  OVER,  PRODUCTION  AND 
DISTRIBUTION  OF  GOODS 
AND  SERVICES 


MONOGRAPH  No.  38 

A  STUDY  OF  THE  CONSTRUCTION  AND  ENFORCE- 
MENT OF  THE  FEDERAL  ANTITRUST  LAWS 


Printed  for  the  use  of  the 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee 


y^l,^?'/',  ivn^/!\)o, 


-UilWED  STATES 

GOVERNMENT  PRINTING  OFFICE 

WASHINGTON  :   1941 


^^ 


NOEIHIASTERN  UNIVERSITY  SCHOOL  of  LAW  LIBRARY 


TEMPORARY  NATIONAL  ECONOMIC  COMMITTEE 

JOSEPH  C.  O'MAHONEY,  Senator  from  Wyoming,  Chairman 

HATTON  W.  SUMMERS,  Representative  from  Texas,  Vice  Chairman 

JAMES  M.  MEAD,  Senator  from  New  York 

WALLACE  H.  WHITE,  Je.,  Senator  from  Maine 

CLYDE  WILLIAMS,  Representative  from  Missouri 

B.  CARROLL  REECE,  Representative  from  Tennessee 

THURMAN  W.  ARNOLD,  Assistant  Attorney  General, 

HUGH  COX,  Special  Assistant  to  the  Attorney  General. 

Representing  the  Department  of  Justice 

SUMNER  T.  PIKE,  Commissioner, 

Representing  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission 

GARLAND  S.  FERGUSON,  Commissioner, 

*EWIN  L.  DAVIS,  Chairman, 

Representing  the  Federal  Trade  Commission 

ISADOR  LUBIN,  Commissioner  of  Labor  Statistics, 

•A.  FORD  HINRICHS,  Chief  Economist,  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics, 

Representing  the  Department  of  Labor 

JOSEPH  J.  O'CONNELL,  Jr.,  Special  Assistant  to  the  General  Counsel 

♦CHARLES  L.  KADES,  Special  Assistant  to  the  General  Counsel, 

Representing  the  Department  of  the  Treasury 

WAYNE  C.  TAYLOR,  Under  Secretary  of  Commerce, 

•M.  JOSEPH  MEEHAN,  Chief  Statistician,  Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce, 

Representing  the  Department  of  Commerce 

LEON  HENDERSON,  Economic  Coordinator 

DEWEY  ANDERSON,  Executive  Secretary 

,^jj  THEODORE  J.  KREPS,  Economic  Adviser 


Monograph  No.  38 

A  STUDY  OF  THE  CONSTRUCTION  AND   ENFORCEMENT  OF   THE 

FEDERAL  ANTITRUST  LAWS 


II 


BY 
MILTON  HANDLER 


en 


ACKNOWLEDGMENT 


This  monograph  was  written  by 

MILTON  HANDLER 

Associate  Professor  of  Law,  Columbia  University  School  of  Law,  and 
Special  Assistant  to  the  General  Counsel,  Treasury  Department 

The  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  is  greatly  indebted 
to  tliis  author  for  his  contribution  to  the  literature  of  the  subject  under 
review. 

The  status  of  the  materials  in  the  volume  is  precisely  the  same  as  that 
of  other  carefully  prepared  testimony  when  given  by  individual  witnesses; 
it  is  information  submitted  for  Committee  deliberation.  No  matter  what 
the  official  capacity  of  the  witness  or  author  may  be,  the  publication  of  his 
testimony,  report,  or  monograph  by  the  Committee  in  no  way  signifies  nor 
implies  assent  to,  or  approval  of,  any  of  the  facts,  opinion,  or  recommen- 
dations, nor  acceptance  thereof  in  whole  or  in  ptart  by  the  members  of  the 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  individually  or  collectively. 
Sole  and  undivided  responsibility  for  every  statement  in  such  testimony, 
reports,  or  monographs  rests  entirely  upon  the  respective  authors. 

(Signed)     Joseph  C,  O'Mahoney, 
Chairman,  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee. 

m 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


Page 

I.  Letter  of  transmittal vii 

II.  Introduction 1 

III.  Substantive  law 2 

A.  Introductory . 3 

B.  The  rule  of  reason 3 

1.  Necessity 3 

2.  Meaning 3 

3.  Application  to  ancillary  restraints  of  trade 3 

4.  Applicability  to  nonancillary  restraints  of  trade 4 

5.  Divergent  rules  at  common  law 4 

6.  Initial  rejection  of  the  rule  of  reason  by  the  Supreme 

Court 5 

a.  Peckham,  J.,  in  United  States  v.  Trans-Missouri 

Freight  Association 5 

b.  Taft,  J.,  in  Addyston  Pipe  case 6 

c.  White,  C.  J.,  in  Standard  Oil  of  New  Jersey  v. 

United  States 7 

7.  Adoption  of  the  rule  of  reason 7 

8.  Effects  of  such  adoption 8 

C.  Activities  of  loose-knit  confederations 9 

1.  Direct  price-6xing 9 

a.  Analysis  of  practice 9 

b.  Effects  of  practice 10 

c.  Summary  of  authorities 10 

2.  Control  of  output 14 

a.  Analysis  of  practice 14 

b.  State  of  the  authorities 14 

c.  Suggestions. 16 

3.  Sharing  markets 16 

a.  Analysis  of  practice 16 

b.  Summary  of  authorities 17 

4.  Collection  and  dissemination  of  trade  statistics  and 

of  open-price  systems 18 

a.  Description  of  practice --  18 

b.  Summary  of  authorities 19 

c.  Enumeration  of  important  features  of  statis- 

tical programs 19 

d.  Appraisal  of  the  legality  of  the  principal  fea- 

tures of  statistical  programs 20 

(1)  Nonavailability    to    purchasers    and 

the  public  of  the  information  col- 
lected and  disseminated 20 

(2)  Closed  and  past  transactions 21 

(3)  Filing  of  current  and  future  prices--  22 

(4)  Agreement  to  adhere  to  filed  price  for 

a  fixed  period  of  time  or  not  to 
deviate    therefrom    without    prior 

notice 23 

(5)  Waiting  period 23 

(6)  Disclosure   of   individual   price   and 

production  data 24 

(7)  Interpretative  data 25 

(8)  Meetings  and  discussions 25 

(9)  Recommendations,     persuasion,     or 

pressure  concerning  price  or  pro- 
duction policies 25 

(10)  Penalties 26 

(11)  Miscellaneous     factors     that     may 

affect    the    legality    of    statistical 

programs 26 

(a)  Competitive  texture  of  the 

industry 26 

(b)  Demoralized    state    of    the 

industry 26 

(c)  Effect  on  price 27 

(d)  Regulatory  agency 27 

V 


yi  TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 

III.  Substantive  law— Continued.                      .           ^     ^.        ■,  t, 

C.  Activities  of  loose-knit  confederations — Continued.  -t^age 

e.  Suggestions 27 

f.  Conclusions 28 

5.  Degree  of  market  control 29 

a.  De6nitions  of  terms 29 

b.  Summary  of  authorities 30 

c.  Suggestions 34 

6.  Price  uniformity  and  identical  bids 35 

a.  Description  of  practices 35 

b.  Analysis  of  price  uniformity 36 

c.  State  of  the  authorities 37 

d.  Suggestions 38 

7.  Price  leadership 40 

a.  Analysis  of  practice 40 

b.  State  of  the  authorities 42 

c.  Suggestions 43 

d.  Conclusions 45 

8.  Miscellaneous  practices 45 

D.  Mergers  and  consolidations 46 

1.  SugarTrust 46 

2.  Northern  Securities  case 47 

3.  Oil  and  Tobacco  Trusts 49 

4.  Terminal  case 53 

5.  Railroad  cases 57 

6.  Shoe  Machinery  Trust 59 

7.  Steel  Corporation 63 

8.  Anthracite  coal  cases 66 

9.  Anaconda  merger 71 

10.  International  Harvester  consolidation 72 

11.  Recapitulation 74 

a.  Size  of  the  capital  combination. and  its  posi- 

tion in  the  industry 74 

b.  Intent  to  monopolize 77 

c.  Indulgence  in  predatory  practices 79 

d.  Monopoly  power  to  exclude  competitors  or  to 

fix  prices 80 

e.  Existence  of  actvial  competition  in  the  indus- 

try after  the  completion  of  the  merger 80 

f .  Potential  competition 81 

g.  Form  of  combination 82 

h.  Other  justifications 82 

12.  Rule  of  reason  in  monopoly  cases 83 

13.  Dissolution 84 

14.  Relation  of  monopoly  to  restraint  of  trade 84 

1 5.  Stock  acquisitions  and  holding  companies 86 

IV.  Antitrust  enforcement 90 

A.  The  inadequacy  of  appropriations  and  personnel 90 

B.  Complexity  of  antitrust  litigation    and    the    inadequacies   of 

procedure 90 

C.  Recommendations 92 

1.  Registration  of  trade  groups 92 

2.  Declaratory  rulings  and  legality  of  capital  combina- 

tions  1 95 

3.  Open,    comprehensive,    and   complete   files  on  major 

industries 96 

4.  Specification  of  offenses 96 

5.  Implementation  of  the  statute 97 

6.  Distressed  industries 99 

7.  Existing  concentration  of  industry 99 

V.  Conclusion . 100 

VI.  Appendix 1 101 


LETTER  OF  TRANSMITTAL 


Hon.  Joseph  C.  O'Mahoney, 

Chairman,  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee, 
Washington,  D.  C. 

My  Dear  Senator:  I  have  the  honor  to  submit  for  the  record  a 
study  of  the  construction  and  enforcement  of  the  Federal  antitrust 
hiws,  prepared  in  the  Treasury  Department  for  the  Temporary 
National  Economic  Committee. 

You  will  recall  that  when  the  Committee  first  began  its  work 
Herman  Oliphant,  then  the  General  Counsel  for  the  Treasury  Depart- 
ment, was  the  Treasury  representative  on  the  Committee.  Because 
he  was  a  recognized  authority  in  the  field  of  trade  regulation,  to  this 
Department  was  assigned  the  preparation  of  a  siu-vey  of  the  statutes 
and  decisions  imder  the  antitrust  laws.  The  work  was  begun  under 
Mr.  Oliphant's  direction  and  with  Milton  Handler,  associate  professor 
of  law,  Columbia  University  school  of  law,  and  Special  Assistant  to 
the  General  Counsel  of  this  Department,  in  immediate  charge  of  the 
work.  Since  the  unfortunate  and  untimely  death  of  Mr.  Oliphant  on 
January  11,  1939,  the  work  has  been  continued  and  brought  to  a  con- 
clusion by  Mr.  Handler,  under  the  general  supervision  of  the  writer  as 
the  Treasury  representative  on  the  Committee. 

In  the  collection  of  the  material  which  forms  the  basis  for  the  study 
Mr.  Handler  had  the  benefit  of  workers  both  within  and  without  the 
Department.  However,  the  legal  conclusions  reached  in  the  report, 
as  well  as  the  views  expressed  therein  as  to  the  desirability  of  certain 
changes  in  the  laws  relating  to  monopoly,  restraint  of  trade,  and 
unfair  competition,  are  those  of  Mr.  Handler  and  not  of  the  Depart- 
ment, which  does  not  express  any  view  as  regards  any  of  the  subjects 
under  discussion  in  the  report.  However,  the  writer  has  no  hestitancy 
in  saying  that  he  is  personally  in  accord  with  the  views  expressed  and 
believes  that  they  merit  the  carefid  consideration  of  the  Committee. 
Sincerely  yom's, 

Joseph  J.  O'Connell,  Jr., 
Special  Assistant  to  the  General  Counsel,  Department  of  the  Treasury. 

February  1,  1941. 

vn 


INTRODUCTION  1 

A  half  century  has  elapsed  since  Congress  gave  expression  in  legisla- 
tion to  the  American  faith  in  free  competition  as  a  system  of  economic 
organization  and  control.  By  this  legislation,  it  sought  to  preserve 
competition  from  the  extinction  which  threatened  it.  These  50 
years  have  witnessed  many  changes  in  the  American  way  of  life  and  in 
the  structure  and  operation  of  our  business  system.  The  dreaded 
trusts  of  the  past  century  are  but  pygmies  in  comparison  with  our 
present  day  industrial  giants.  Activities  subversive  of  competition 
are  today  conducted  on  a  scale  and  imder  forms  beyond  the  conception 
of  the  framers  of  the  legislation  of  1890.  Competition  still  exists,  but 
it  has  been  compromised  by  organizations,  arrangements,  and  practices 
which  are  alien  to  its  spuit  and  which  impede  its  proper  functioning. 

Those  who  have  lost  faith  in  competitive  institutions  attribute  this 
failure  to  the  allegedly  mistaken  purpose  of  the  Sherman  Law.  To 
them,  competition  has  been  tried  and  foimd  wanting;  they  indict  it  as 
inefficient,  wasteful,  and  obsolete;  it  is  an  archaic  system,  contrived 
for  the  needs  of  petty  trade  but  utterly  unsuited  for  the  highly 
organized  and  war-strained  economy  of  the  twentieth  century. 
Others  profess  agreement  with  the  objectives  of  the  legislation  which 
they  characterize  as  laudable  but  unattainable;  the  Sherman  Act,  to 
their  way  of  thinking,  like  national  prohibition,  is  incapable  of 
enforcement. 

Under  these  viewpoints  the  Sherman  law  is  beyond  redemption  and 
must  give  way  to  new  legislation  based  upon  different  conceptions 
and  pointed  toward  different  objectives. 

The  failure  of  a  statute,  however,  may  result  not  from  a  misconceived 
policy  but  from  faulty  draftsmanship  or  from  frustrating  judicial  con- 
struction; the  objectives  of  a  law  may  remain  unachieved  not  because 
they  are  unattainable  but  because  they  have  not  been  earnestly  pur- 
sued by  vigorous,  impartial,  and  effective  enforcement.  Laws  to  a 
large  extent  are  only  as  effective  as  the  men  who  enforce  them.  The 
procedural  and  substantive  limitations  of  a  statute  may  be  overcome 
by  the  resourcefulness  and  energy  of  enforcement  agencies,  but  laws, 
no  matter  how  perfect,  are  never  self-executing,  and  without  sufficient 
manpower,  remain  a  pious  aspu-ation  untranslated  from  the  realm  of 
words  to  that  of  action.  A  law  which  has  never  been  truly  enforced 
cannot  be  said  to  be  unenforceable. 

The  wisdom  of  the  economic  philosophy  underlying  the  Sherman 
Act  has  been  considered  from  various  angles  by  the  Temporary  Na- 
tional Economic  Committee  in  its  extensive  hearings  and  has  been  the 
subject  of  study,  direct  and  indirect,  on  the  part  of  many  of  the  other 
agencies  associated  in  this  investigation.  The  Treasury's  part  in  the 
general  diagnosis  has  been  the  examination  of  (1)  the  substantive  and 

'  Grateful  acknowledgment  is  made  to  Lawrence  Eno,  Esq.,  of  the  New  York  Bar,  for  his  valuable  assist- 
ance in  the  preparation  of  that  part  of  this  report  dealing  with  the  application  of  the  antitrust  laws  to  loose- 
knit  confederations  and  to  Sidney  Barrows  for  assisting  with  the  proofs. 

1 


2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

procedural  provisions  of  the  antitrust  laws,  (2)  the  court  decisions  con- 
struing such  laws,  and  (3)  the  agencies  and  methods  of  enforcement,  to 
ascertain  whether  shortcomings  of  statute,  judicial  decision,  or  ma- 
chinery of  enforcement  may  fairly  be  held  accountable,  in  whole  or 
in  part,  for  this  failure  of  our  antitrust  legislation.  This  report 
embodies  the  results  of  the  various  studies  conducted  by  the  Treasury, 
stated  as  succinctly  and  summarily  as  is  possible. 

SUBSTANTIVE  LAW 

The  conduct  condemned  by  the  Sherman  Act  falls  into  two  general 
categories,  (1)  restraint  of  trade,  and  (2)  monopoly.  What  is  a 
restraint  of  trade  and  what  constitutes  a  monopoly  are  left  undefined 
by  the  statute.  The  legal  repression  of  restraint  of  trade  and  monop- 
oly long  antedated  this  legislation,  both  terms  having  a  common  law 
significance.  The  case-law  development  of  the  concept  of  restraint 
of  trade  had  been  extensive,  the  courts  over  a  long  period  of  years 
having  passed  upon  the  legality  of  a  wide  variety  of  agreements  and 
concerted  arrangements.  The  statute,  read  in  the  light  of  this  body 
of  authority,  possessed  a  concreteness  of  meaning  not  otherwise  appar- 
ent on  its  face.  Less  helpful,  however,  were  the  common  law  prece- 
dents dealing  with  monopoly  since  they  treated  of  situations  factually 
and  conceptually  different  from  those  arising  after  1890. 

Enforcement  officials  were  called  upon  to  apply  the  statute  to  two 
types  of  combines,  (1)  loose-laait  confederations  and  (2)  close-knit 
integrations.  The  loose-knit  combinations  involved  the  elimination 
of  competition  among  independent  business  enterprises  either  by  vol- 
untary accord  thi'ough  the  fixation  of  prices,  allotment  of  customers, 
division  of  territories,  and  curtailment  of  production  or  to  the  involun- 
tary exclusion  of  competitors  through  boycotts  and  similar  restrictive 
practices.  The  close-knit  integrations  related  to  the  combination  of 
companies  by  trust,  holding  company,  merger,  or  consolidation. 

What  criterion  was  to  be  applied  by  the  courts  in  determining  the 
legality  of  such  concerted  action  on  the  part  of  business  men?  Was 
every  arrangement  between  competitors  by  wliich  prices  were  directly 
fixed  or  indirectly  affected  milawful,  whether  or  not  the  parties  to  the 
combine  were  in  substantial  control  of  the  trade  or  industry  and  in  a 
position  to  dictate  the  market  price?  Did  the  statute  condemn  agree- 
ments setting  reasonable  prices?  Could  business  men  resort  to  price 
arrangements  as  a  corrective  to  a  competition  which  no  matter  how 
benevolent  in  theory  was  ruinous  in  practice?  Was  every  acquisition 
of  the  corporate  stock  or  physical  assets  of  a  competitor — even  the 
formation  of  a  partnership — interdicted  by  the  law?  If  some  integra- 
tion was  permissible,  at  what  point  did  the  combination  of  companies 
become  unlawful? 

What  guidance  did  the  legislation  itself  provide  to  the  solution  of 
these  perplexing  problems?  The  statute  in  section  1  condemned  every 
contract,  combination,  or  conspiracy,  in  the  form  of  a  trust  or  other- 
wise, in  restraint  of  trade  or  commerce  among  the  several  States.  Did 
this  mean  that  every  agreement  between  two  or  more  competitors 
constituting  a  technical  restraint  was  prohibited?  Was  every  pur- 
chase of  a  competing  business,  no  matter  how  extenuating  the  cir- 
cumstances, forbidden? 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  3 

Tho  broad  inclusiveness  and  iincomproniisin<^  severity  of  the  statu- 
tory language  seemed  to  permit  of  but  one  answer.  A  literal  reading 
of  the  law  would  have  condemned  every  arrangement  deemed  a  re- 
straint of  trade  at  common  law,  including  the  familiar  covenants  not 
to  compete  ancillary  to  the  sale  and  purchase  of  a  going  business  or 
appurtenant  to  a  contract  of  employment.  It  was  to  avoid  the 
absurdities  of  such  a  construction  that  the  rule  of  reason  was  adopted. 

In  view  of  the  widespread  misconception  of  the  rule  of  reason,  a  few 
words  concerning  its  genesis  and  scope  may  not  be  inappropriate. 

RULE  OF  REASON 

The  concept  of  reasonableness  is  not  unfamiliar  to  our  law.  A 
standard  of  reason  is  employed  in  many  branches  of  law  to  measure 
the  legality  of  human  conduct.  In  some  fields  the  standard  rises 
barely  above  the  unanalyzed  subjective  reaction  of  those  entrusted 
with  its  application.  In  other  fields,  the  rule  of  reason  is  a  term  of 
art  with  a  history  and  a  logic  of  its  own.  As  the  term  "reasonable- 
ness" itself  invites  a  looseness  of  analysis,  and  in  view  of  the  numerous 
clusters  of  meaning  that  envelope  its  use  in  the  law,  it  is  particularly 
important  that  its  precise  meaning  in  the  field  of  restraint  of  trade 
be  clearly  outlined. 

Reason  as  the  test  of  legality  of  a  restraint  of  trade  was  first  applied 
in  the  classic  case  of  Mitchel  v.  Reynolds}  Its  use  was  initially  con- 
fined to  the  field  of  ancillary  restraints  ^  such  as  covenants  by  sellers 
not  to  compete  with  their  purchasers  or  agreements  not  to  compete 
on  the  part  of  employees,  purchasers,  lessors,  lessees,  and  partxiers. 
The  reasonableness  of  an  ancillary  restraint  was  determined  in  general 
by  the  needs  of  the  convenantee  (i.  e.,  the  person  in  whose  favor  the 
covenant  was  given) ,  the  consequences  of  the  restraint  upon  the  cove- 
nantor, and  the  effect  of  the  restriction  on  the  public.  Primary  em- 
phasis was  given  to  the  spatial  and  temporal  scope  of  the  restriction, 
and  agreements  were  generally  upheld  if  no  broader  in  area  and  no 
longer  in  time  than  the  needs  of  the  covenantee  required.  A  vast 
body  of  learning  has  developed  in  respect  of  the  reasonableness  of 
ancillary  agreements  not  to  compete  and  numerous  and  minute  dis- 
tinctions have  been  drawn,  none  of  which  is  material  to  the  present 
inquiry.  A  convenient  summary  of  the  present  law  on  the  subject 
is  to  be  found  in  the  Restatement  of  the  Law  of  Contracts,  prepared 
and  published  under  the  auspices  of  the  American  Law  Institute,  the 

1 1  p.  Wms.  181,  24  Eng.  Rep.  347  (1711). 

2  By  an  ancillary  restraint  is  meant  an  agreement  which,  though  restrictive  of  competition,  is  an  integral 
part  of  a  larger,  lawful  transaction.  The  historic  examples  of  such  ancillary  restrictions  are  the  agreement 
of  a  seller  of  a  business  as  part  of  the  contract  of  sale  not  to  compete  with  his  purchaser,  the  agreement  of 
an  employee  not  to  compete  with  his  employer  after  the  conclusion  of  his  employment,  an  agreement  by- 
partners  not  to  compete  with  the  partnership,  an  agreement  by  a  purchaser  not  to  use  the  article  purchased 
in  competition  with  the  seller  and  restrictions  in  leases  in  respect  of  the  use  of  the  leased  premises  or  of  other 
premises  owned  by  the  landlord.  See  Handler,  Restraint  of  Trade  (1924),  ISEncyc.  Soc.  Sciences  339.  For 
the  leading  cases  and  selected  bibliography,  see  Handler,  Cases  on  Trade  Regulation  (1937)  c.  3. 


4  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

pertinent  declaration  of  which  is  set  forth  in  a  footnote.^  For  present 
purposes  it  is  sufficient  to  note  that  the  genesis  and  principal  field 
of  application  of  the  rule  of  reason  has  been  in  relation  to  the  familiar 
ancillary  restraints  of  trade. 

Scholars  and  courts  have  been  greatly  exercised  as  to  whether  the 
common  law  applied  the  rule  of  reason  to  restraints  of  competition 
which  were  not  ancillary  to  some  major  transaction.^  The  evidence 
is  conflicting  and  has  given  rise  to  divergent  interpretations.  The 
failure  to  recognize  that  the  "common  law"  is  but  a  metaphorical 
expression  and  that  there  are  as  many  common  laws  as  there  are 
independent  judicial  systems  has  been  the  principal  cause  of  con- 
fusion. The  fact  is  that  the  English  and  some  American  courts 
regarded  the  rule  of  reason  as  applicable  to  horizontal  arrangements 
between  competitors,  which  curbed,  controlled,  or  eliminated  compe- 
tition, and  which  were  not  ancillary  to  any  major  transaction.  Many 
American  courts,  on  the  contrary,  either  explicitly  regarded  the  rule 
of  reason  as  inapplicable  to  such  arrangements,  or,  without  mention 
of  the  rule,  branded  the  activities  under  consideration  as  unlawful. 
Thus,  there  were  at  least  three  discernible  trends  in  the  authorities 
prior  to  1890.  Under  what  was  probably  the  prevailing  view,  all 
agreements  among  persons  engaged  in  the  same  trade,  industry,  or 
line  of  commerce,  whereby  competition  was  eliminated  or  reduced 
either  through  the  fixation  of  prices,  the  control  of  output,  the  pooling 
of  profits,  the  division  of  markets  or  other  devices  inconsistent  with 
competitive  institutions,  were  unlawful,  whether  or  not  the  prices 
or  other  market  conditions  noncompetitively  established  were  reason- 
able, whether  or  not  the  arrangement  was  designed  to  halt  a  ruinous 
competition  and  whether  or  not  the  formation  of  the  combination 
was  inspired  by  good  motives.  Under  another  view,  agreements  by 
minority  groups  without  control  of  the  market  were  upheld  if  com- 
petition in  the  market  itself  remained  unaffected,  despite  the  fact  that 
competition  among  the  parties  themselves  was  either  eliminated  or 
controlled.  The  rule  of  reason  under  this  view  meant  in  essence  the 
absence  of  monopoly  power.     Under  a  third  view,  legality  was  not 

3  5513.  Definition  of  a  Bargain  in  Restraint  of  Trade.    A  bargain  is  in  restraint  of  trade  when  its  perform- 
ance would  limit  competition  in  any  business  or  restrict  a  promisor  in  the  e.xercise  of  a  gainful  occupation. 

§514.  When  a  Bargain  in  liestraint  of  Trade  is  Illegal.    A  bargain  in  restraint  of  trade  is  illegal  if  the 
restraint  is  unreasonable. 

§51.5.  When  a  Restraint  of  Trade  is  Unreasonable.    A  restraint  of  trade  is  unreasonable,  in  the  absence  of 
statutory  authorization  or  dominant  social  or  economic  justification,  if  it- 
Co)  is  greater  than  is  required  for  the  protection  of  the  person  for  whose  benefit  the  restraint  is  imposed; 

or 
(^)  imposes  undue  hardship  upon  the  person  restricted,  or 

(c)  tends  to  create,  or  has  for  its  purpose  to  create,  a  monopoly,  or  to  control  prices  or  to  limit  produc- 

tion artificially,  or 

(d)  unreasonably  restricts  the  alienation  or  use  of  anything  that  is  a  subject  of  property,  or 

(e)  is  based  on  a  promise  to  refrain  from  competition  and  is  not  ancillary  either  to  a  contract  for  the 

transfer  of  good-will  or  other  subject  of  property  or  to  an  existing  employment  or  contract  of 
employment. 
§516.  Instances  of  Reasonable  Restraints.    The  following  bargains  do  not  impose  unreasonable  restraints 
of  trade  unless  effecting,  or  forming  part  of  a  plan  to  effect,  a  monopoly: 

(a)  A  bargain  by  the  transferor  of  property  or  of  a  business  not  to  compete  with  the  buyer  in  such  a  way 

as  to  injure  the  value  of  the  property  or  business  sold: 
(6)  A  bargain  by  the  buyer  or  lessee  of  property  or  of  a  business  not  to  use  it  in  competition  with  or  to 
the  injury  of  the  seller  or  lessor: 

(c)  Abargain  to  enter  into  partnership  with  an  actual  or  possible  competitor; 

(d)  Abargain  by  a  partner  not  to  interfere  by  competition  or  otherwise  with  the  business  of  the  part- 

nership while  it  continues,  or  subject  to  reasonable  limitations  after  his  retirement; 
(«)  A  bargain  to  deal  exclusively  with  another; 

(/)   A  bargain  by  an  a.ssistant,  servant,  or  agent  not  to  compete  with  his  employer,  or  principal,  during 
the  term  of  the  employment  or  agency,  or  thereafter,  within  such  territory  and  during  such  time 
as  may  be  rea.sonably  necessary  for  the  protection  of  the  employer  or  principal,  without  imposing 
undue  hardshi[)  on  the  employee  or  agent. 
*  All  restrictions  on  competition  which  are  not  part  of  some  larger  lawful  transaction  are  deemed  non- 
ancillary.    Examples  arc  naked  agreements  not  to  compete,  agreements  sharing  markets,  dividing  terri- 
tories, controlling  output,  and  fixing  prices. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  5 

limited  to  the  activities  of  minority  groups  but  extended  to  arrange- 
ments by  those  with  monopoly  power  provided  their  monopoly  posi- 
tion was  not  abused.  Even  price-fixing  agreements  might  be  upheld 
under  this  view  if  the  prices  established  were  reasonable  and  the  ob- 
jects of  the  combine  were  not  the  exploitation  of  the  public  but  the 
rectification  of  intolerable  industrial  conditions.* 

To  speak  of  a  common  law  in  light  of  such  divergences  of  ruling  is 
to  court  confusion. 

The  Supreme  Court,  as  is  commonly  known,  originally  rejected  the 
rule  of  reason,  holding  it  inapplicable  to  proceedings  under  the  Sher- 
man Act.^  Primacy  was  given  to  the  word  "every"  in  section  1  of 
the  statute.  It  was  felt  that  there  was  no  room  under  the  wording 
of  the  statute  for  the  adoption  of  common  law  views  of  legality,  as- 
suming the  common  law  countenanced  horizontal,  non-ancillary  re- 
strictions of  competition.  The  pith  of  this  ruling  appears  in  the  fol- 
lowing excerpts  from  the  opinion  of  Mr,  Justice  Peckham  in  United 
States  V.  Trans-Missouri  Freight  Assn.:  ' 

*  *  *  'pjj^p  next  question  to  be  discussed  is  as  to  wnat  is  the  true  construction 
of  the  statute,  assuming  that  it  applies  to  common  carriers  by  railroad  *  *  *. 
Is  it  confined  to  a  contract  or  combination  which  is  only  in  unreasonable  restraint 
of  trade  or  commerce,  or  does  it  include  what  the  language  of  the  act  plainljy  and 
and  in  terms  covers,  all  contracts  of  that  nature?     *     *     * 

It  is  now  with  much  amplification  of  argument  urged  that  the  statute,  in 
declaring  illegal  every  combination  in  the  form  of  trust  or  otherwise,  or  conspiracy 
in  restraint  of  trade  or  commerce,  does  not  mean  what  the  language  used  therein 
plainly  imports,  but  that  it  only  means  to  declare  illegal  any  such  contract  which 
is  in  unreasonable  restraint  of  trade,  while  leaving  all  others  unaffected  by  the 
provisions  of  the  act;  that  the  common  law  meaning  of  the  term  "contract  in 
restraint  of  trade"  includes  only  such  contracts  as  are  in  unreasonable  restraint 
of  trade,  and  when  that  term  is  used  in  the  Federal  statute  it  is  net  intended  to 
include  all  contracts  in  restraint  of  trade,  but  only  those  which  are  in  unreasonable 
restraint  thereof. 

The  term  is  not  of  such  limited  signification.  Contracts  in  restraint  of  trade 
have  been  known  and  spoken  of  for  hundreds  of  years  both  in  England  and  in 
this  country,  and  the  term  includes  all  kinds  of  those  contracts  which  in  fact 
restrain  or  may  restrain  trade.  Some  of  such  contracts  have  been  held  void  and 
unenforceable  in  the  courts  by  reason  of  their  restraint  being  unreasonable,  while 
others  have  been  held  valid  because  they  were  not  of  that  nature.  A  contract 
may  be  in  restraint  of  trade  and  still  be  valid  at  common  law.  Although  valid, 
it  is  nevertheless  a  contract  in  restraint  of  trade,  and  would  be  so  described  either 
at  common  law  or  elsewhere.  By  the  simple  use  of  the  term  "contract  in  restraint 
of  trade,"  all  contracts  of  that  nature,  whether  valid  or  otherwise,  would  be  in- 
cluded, and  not  alone  that  kind  of  contract  which  was  invalid  and  unenforceable 
as  being  in  unreasonable  restraint  of  trade.  When,  therefore,  the  body  of  an 
act  pronounces  as  illegal  every  contract  or  combination  in  restraint  of  trade  or 
coinmerce  among  the  several  States,  etc.,  the  plain  and  ordinary  meaning  of  such 
language  is  not  limited  to  that  kind  of  contract  alone  which  is  in  unreasonable 
restraint  of  trade,  but  all  contracts  are  included  in  such  language,  and  no  exception 
or  limitation  can  be  added  without  placing  in  the  act  that  which  has  been  omitted 
by  Congress     *     *     *_ 

The  plaintiffs  are,  however,  under  no  obligation  in  order  to  maintain  this  action 
to  show  that  by  the  common  law  all  agreements  among  competing  railroad 
companies  to  keep  up  rates  to  such  as  are  reasonable  were  void  as  in  restraint  of 
trade  or  commerce.  There  are  many  cases  which  look  in  that  direction  if  they 
do  not  precisely  decide  that  point  *  *  *.  But  assuming  that  agreements  of 
this  nature  are  not  void  at  common  law  and  that  the  various  cases  cited  by  the 
learned  courts  below  show  it,  the  answer  to  the  statement  of  their  validity  now  is 
to  be  found  in  the  terms  of  the  statute  under  consideration     *     *     *. 


'  (1932)  32  Col.  L.  Rev.  291,  297;  Peppin,  Price-Fixing  Agreements  Under  the  Sherman  Anti-Trust  Law, 
(1940)  28  Calif.  L.  Rev.  297. 

6  United  States  v.  Trans-Missouri  Freight  Assn.  (1897)  166  U.  S.  290;  United  States  v.  Joint  Traffic  Assn. 
(1898),  171  U.  S.  505;  Addiiston  Pipe  and  Steel  Co.  v.  United  States  (1899),  175  U.  S.  211. 

'  (1897)  166  U.  S.  290,  327,  334. 


g  CONCETNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  approach  of  Judge  Taft  in  his  celebrated  and  oft-quoted  opinion 
in  the  Addyston  Pipe  case  ^  was  quite  different.  The  basis  of  his  rejec- 
tion of  the  rule  of  reason  was  not  the  presence  of  the  word  "every"  in 
section  1  but  the  fact  that  the  common  law  restricted  the  application 
of  the  rule  of  reason  to  the  ancillary  restraints  and  condemned  all 
nonancillary  restrictions  on  competition.  Hence,  even  were  it 
assumed  that  the  statute  codified  the  common  law,  there  would  be  no 
room  for  the  application  of  the  rule  of  reason  to  combinations  in 
restraint  of  trade.  His  conclusions  from  a  thorough  examination  of 
the  common-law  precedents  were  as  follows: 

For  the  reasons  given,  then,  covenants  in  partial  restraint  of  trade  are  generally 
upheld  as  valid  when  they  are  agreements  (1)  by  the  seller  of  property  or  business 
not  to  compete  with  the  buyer  in  such  a  way  as  to  derogate  from  the  value  of  the 
property  or  business  sold;  (2)  by  a  retiring  partner  not  to  compete  with  the  firm; 
(3)  by  a  partner  pending  the  partnership  not  to  do  anything  to  interfere,  by  com- 
petition or  otherwise,  with  the  business  of  the  firm;  (4)  by  the  buyer  of  property 
not  to  use  the  same  in  competition  with  the  business  retained  by  the  seller;  and  (5) 
by  an  assistant,  servant,  or  agent  not  to  compete  with  his  master  or  employer 
after  the  expiration  of  his  time  of  service.  Before  such  agreements  are  upheld, 
however,  the  court  must  find  that  the  restraints  attempted  thereby  are  reasonably 
necessary  (1,  2,  and  3)  to  the  enjoyment  by  the  buyer  of  the  property,  goodwill, 
or  interest  in  the  partnership  bought;  or  (4)  to  the  legitimate  ends  of  the  exist- 
ing partnership;  or  (5)  to  the  prevention  of  possible  injury  to  the  business  of  the 
seller  from  use  by  the  buyer  of  the  thing  sold;  or  (6)  to  protection  from  the 
danger  of  loss  to  the  employer's  business  caused  by  the  unjust  use  on  the  part  of 
the  employee  of  the  confidential  knowledge  acquired  in  such  business     *     *     *_ 

It  would  be  stating  it  too  strongly  to  say  that  these  five  classes  of  covenants  in 
restraint  of  trade  include  all  of  those  upheld  as  valid  at  the  common  law;  but  it 
would  certainly  seem  to  follow  from  the  tests  laid  down  for  determining  the  validity 
of  such  an  agreement  that  no  conventional  restraint  of  trade  can  be  enforced  unless 
the  covenant  embodying  it  is  merely  ancillary  to  the  main  purpose  of  a  lawful 
contract,  and  necessary  to  protect  the  covenantee  in  the  enjoyment  of  the  legiti- 
mate fruits  of  the  contract,  or  to  protect  him  from  the  dangers  of  an  unjust  use  of 
those  fruits  by  the  other  party     *     *     * 

This  very  statement  of  the  rule  implies  that  the  contract  must  be  one  in  which 
there  is  a  main  purpose,  to  which  the  covenant  in  restraint  of  trade  is  merely 
ancillary.  The  covenant  is  inserted  only  to  protect  one  of  the  parties  from  the 
injury  which,  in  the  execution  of  the  contract  or  enjoyment  of  its  fruits,  he  may 
suffer  from  the  unrestrained  competition  of  the  other.  The  main  purpose  of  the 
contract  suggests  the  measure  of  protection  needed,  and  furnishes  a  sufficiently 
uniform  standard  by  which  the  validity  of  such  restraints  may  be  judicially  deter- 
mined. In  such  a  case,  if  the  restraint  exceeds  the  necessity  presented  by  the 
main  purpose  of  the  contract,  it  is  void  for  two  reasons:  First,  because  it  oppresses 
the  covenantor,  without  any  corresponding  benefit  to  the  covenantee;  and,  second, 
because  it  tends  to  a  monopoly.  But  where  the  sole  object  of  both  parties  in 
making  the  contract  as  expressed  therein  is  merely  to  restrain  competition,  and 
enhance  or  maintain  prices,  it  would  seem  that  there  was  nothing  to  justify  or  excuse 
the  restraint,  that  it  would  necessarily  have  a  tendency  to  monopoly,  and  there- 
fore would  be  void.  In  such  a  case  there  is  no  measure  of  what  is  necessary  to  the 
protection  of  either  party,  except  the  vague  and  varying  opinion  of  judges  as  to 
how  much,  on  principles  of  political  economy,  men  ought  to  be  allowed  to  restrain 
competition.  There  is  in  such  contracts  no  main  lawful  purpose,  to  subserve 
which  partial  restraint  is  permitted,  and  by  which  its  reasonableness  is  measured, 
but  the  sole  object  is  to  restrain  trade  in  order  to  avoid  the  competition  which 
it  has  always  been  the  policy  of  the  common  law  to  foster     *     *     * 

*  *  *  It  is  true  that  there  are  some  cases  in  which  the  courts,  mistaking, 
as  we  conceive,  the  proper  limits  of  the  relaxation  of  the  rules  for  determining  the 
unreasonableness  of  restraints  of  trade,  have  set  sail  on  a  sea  of  doubt,  and  have 
assumed  the  power  to  say,  in  respect  to  contracts  which  have  no  other  purpose  and 
no  other  consideration  on  either  side  than  the  mutual  restraint  of  the  parties, 
how  much  restraint  of  competition  is  in  the  public  interest,  and  how  much  is  not. 

•  (1898)  86  Fed.  271.  281. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  7 

The  manifest  danger  in  the  administration  of  justice  according  to  so  shifting, 
vague,  and  indeterminate  a  standard  would  seem  to  be  a  strong  reason  against 
adopting  it     *     *     *.• 

Like  Judge  Taft,  Chief  Justice  White  assumed  that  the  statute 
codified  the  coiiiinon  law,  but  he  derived  a  totally  different  set  of 
conclusions  from  this  initial  premise.  His  examination  of  the  common 
law  satisfied  him  that  the  standard  of  reason  was  applied  to  all  re- 
straints, ancillary  and  nonancillary,  and  that  the  term  restraint  of 
trade  was  used  at  common  law  to  signify  an  unreasonable  restriction 
of  competition.  A  reasonable  restraint  of  trade  was  to  him  a  contra- 
diction in  terms — if  the  restriction  was  reasonable  it  was  not  a  restraint 
of  trade;  if  a  restraint  of  trade,  it  was  by  definition  unreasonable. 
By  ascribing  this  artificial  meaning  to  "restraint  of  trade,"  he  avoided 
the  embarrassment  of  the  word  ''every"  and  imported  the  rule  of 
reason  into  the  statute.  His  thesis  is  expounded  at  considerable 
length  in  Standard  Oil  Co.  oj  New  Jersey  v.  United  States, ^°  but  is  more 
succinctly  expressed  in  United  States  v.  American  Tobacco  Co.^^  as 
follows: 

Applying  the  rule  of  reason  to  the  construction  of  the  statute,  it  was  held  in  the 
Standard  Oil  case  that  as  the  words  "restraint  of  trade"  at  common  law  and  in  the 
law  of  this  country  at  the  time  of  the  adoption  of  the  Antitrust  Act  only  embraced 
acts  or  contracts  or  agreements  or  combinations  which  operated  to  the  prejudice 
of  the  public  interests  by  unduly  restricting  competition  or  unduly  obstructing 
the  due  course  of  trade  or  which,  either  because  of  their  inherent  nature  or  effect 
or  because  of  the  evident  purpose  of  the  acts,  etc.,  injuriously  restrained  trade, 
that  the  words  as  used  in  the  statute  were  desigxied  to  have  and  did  have  but  a 
like  significance  *  *  *.  In  other  words,  it  was  held,  not  that  acts  which  the 
statute  prohibited  could  be  removed  from  the  control  of  its  prohibitions  by  a 
finding  that  they  were  reasonable,  but  that  the  duty  to  interpret  which  inevitably 
arose  from  the  general  character  of  the  term  restraint  of  trade  required  that  the 
words  restraint  of  trade  should  be  given  a  meaning  which  would  not  destroy  the 
individual  right  to  contract  and  render  difficult  if  not  impossible  any  movement 
of  trade  in  the  channels  of  interstate  commerce^ — -the  free  movement  of  which  it 
was  the  purpose  of  the  statute  to  protect. 

The  rule  of  reason  thus  became  part  of  our  antitrust  jurisprudence 
more  than  20  years  after  the  enactment  of  the  Sherman  law. 

The  explanation  for  the  divergent  conclusions  of  these  jurists  is 
not  difficult  to  discover.  The  weight  of  available  evidence  supports 
the  view  that  the  words  of  the  statute  were  used  by  the  Congress  in 
their  common-law  sense. '^  But  Judge  Taft  and  Chief  Justice  White 
had  different  conceptions  of  the  common  law.  This  is  not  surprising 
in  light  of  the  lack  of  uniformity  in  the  juristic  doctrines  of  restraint  of 
trade  prior  to  1890.  While  there  was  no  real  support  for  Chief  Justice 
White's  unorthodox  definition  of  restraint  of  trade,  the  English 
precedents  were  in  accord  with  his  general  conclusion  that  the  validity 
of  all  restraints,  ancillary  and  nonancillary,  was  measured  by  the 
standard  of  reason.  If  the  English  precedents  and  the  few  American 
authorities  following  them  constituted  the  "common  law,"  then  Chief 
Justice  White's  conclusion  was  correct  despite  the  essential  unsound- 
ness of  his  analysis.  If  the  prevailing  view  of  the  American  courts 
which  Judge  Taft  followed  constituted  the  "common  law,"  then  Judge 
Taft's  conclusions  were  correct.  The  truth  of  the  matter,  as  we  have 
seen,  was  that  there  was  more  than  one  common  law  view  and  it  was 

»  For  a  different  elaboration  of  the  rule  of  reason,  see  the  Special  Message  of  President  Taft  to  Congress  on 
the  Anti-Trust  Statute,  December  5,  1911. 
i»  (1911)  221  U.  S.  1. 
11  (1911)  221  U.  S.  106,  179. 
u  Apex  Hosiery  Co.  v.  Leader  (1940),  310  U.  S.  469,  494. 


3  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

not  sufficient  to  assert  that  the  Congress  intended  to  codify  the  com- 
mon law  without  attempting  to  ascertain  which  of  the  common  law 
views  the  legislators  had  in  mind.  To  the  extent  that  the  congres- 
sional purpose  was  obscure,  the  responsibility  of  selection  devolved 
upon  the  courts.  Whichever  view  was  adopted,  violence  necessarily 
was  done  to  the  word  "every"  in  the  statute,  since  under  both  con- 
structions some  restraints  were  permissible. 

Under  the  view  which  prevaUed  before  1911,  all  non-ancillary  re- 
strictions of  competition  such  as  combinations  to  fix  prices,  pool  profits, 
share  markets,  and  control  output  were  unlawful  restraints  prohibited 
by  the  statute.  As  the  reasonableness  of  the  restriction  was  legally 
immaterial,  the  restraint  could  not  be  justified  by  proof  of  good 
motives,  by  the  fact  that  the  combine  lacked  control  of  the  market, 
by  the  reasonableness  of  the  prices  fixed,  or  by  other  extenuating  cir- 
cumstances. After  1911,  agreements  fixing  prices,  dividing  territories, 
and  controlling  production  continued  to  be  unlawful,  but  now  they  were 
denominated  "unreasonable  restraints  of  trade."  No  greater  toler- 
ance of  the  attempted  justification  of  such  restraints  after  the  adoption 
of  the  rule  of  reason  was  exhibited  by  the  courts  than  during  the  period 
of  its  rejection.  In  the  main  and  subject  to  minor  exceptions,  conduct 
which  prior  to  1911  was  condemned  as  an  illegal  restramt  was  held  un- 
reasonable 'per  se  thereafter  and  hence  unlawful. ^^  The  adoption  of 
the  rule  of  reason  effected  more  of  a  change  in  theory  than  in  actual 
doctrine,  insofar  as  loose-knit  combinations  were  concerned.  Greater 
effect  is  to  be  discerned  in  the  field  of  close-knit  combinations,  and  even 
in  the  case  of  the  loose-knits,  there  have  been  occasional  rulings  that 
would  be  inexplicable  save  for  the  rule  of  reason.  Reference  to  these 
rulings  shall  be  made  hereinafter.^* 

There  has  been  a  tendency  to  regard  the  rule  of  reason  as  opening 
the  door  to  the  validation  of  any  scheme  or  device  for  the  curtailment 
of  competition  which  may  be  justified  on  grounds  of  business  expe- 
diency. Reasonable  in  this  context  means  rational,  and  if  an  arrange- 
ment is  not  irrational,  having  regard  for  the  circumstances  of  its  for- 
mation and  operation,  it  should  be  free  from  censure.  Though  oc- 
casional official  utterances  and  isolated  passages  in  judicial  opinions 
may  point  in  this  direction,  the  decisions  of  the  Supreme  Court  in  the 
past  30  years,  viewed  in  their  entirety,  clearly  reject  this  construction 
of  the  rule  of  reason. 

Candor  compels  the  admission  that  the  rulings  of  the  Supreme  Court 
have  not  always  followed  a  consistent  course.  The  rule  of  reason  has 
meant  different  things  to  the  different  Justices.  Despite  the  oscilla- 
tions of  the  Court,  the  gi*eat  majority  of  its  rulings  do  appear,  however, 
to  follow  a  fairly  constant  pattern. 

The  Court  has  recognized  that  the  Sherman  Law  was  intended  to 
preserve  for  the  public  the  protection  and  advantages  of  free  competi- 
tion. Any  device  which  diminishes  this  protection  and  reduces  these 
advantages  is  at  war  with  the  manifest  statutory  purpose.  Whether 
or  not  such  devices  may  further  the  public  good  to  a  greater  extent 
than  free  competition  is  an  inquiry  which  is  not  open  since  the  statute 
accepts  competition  as  the  smnmum  honum  of  our  society.  Conse- 
quently the  reasonableness  of  a  horizontal  agreement  among  competi- 
tors must  be  determined  in  the  light  of  its  compatibility  with  the  ends 

"  (1932)  32  Col.  L.  Rev.  291,  303. 

'<  See  discussion  of  those  cases  in  sections  on  collection  and  dissemination  of  trade  statistics  (p.  18)  and 
degree  of  market  control  (p.  29). 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  9 

to  which  our  antitrust  laws  are  directed.  The  statute  sets  the  frame- 
work for  the  inquiry  into  the  reasonableness  of  particular  practices. 
To  differentiate  between  reasonable  and  unreasonable  price  agreements 
or  between  the  suppression  of  competition  by  those  with  good  motives 
and  those  with  bad  would  be  to  sustain  arrangements  which  are  essen- 
tially antagonistic  to  the  competitive  institutions  which  the  statute 
seeks  to  preserve.  The  rule  of  reason  if  so  extended  would  be  depend- 
ent upon  considerations  of  policy  and  business  expediency  unrelated 
to  the  purposes  of  the  statute.  The  standard  of  reason  though  related 
to  the  statutory  objectives  is  still  vague  and  indefinite.  This  is,  how- 
ever, inherent  in  the  very  nature  of  the  standard.  What  is  and  what 
is  not  consistent  with  the  maintenance  of  competition  is  not  easy  of 
determination.  Integrating  the  rule  of  reason  into  the  purposes  of 
the  legislation  does  not  eliminate  the  element  of  discretion.  It  does, 
however,  establish  the  metes  and  bounds  of  such  discretion  and  pre- 
cludes the  voyage  upon  the  chartless  sea  of  doubt  which  was  so  greatly 
feared  by  Judge  Taft. 

In  short,  then,  the  rule  of  reason  has  introduced  flexibility  into  our 
laws  regulating  business  competition  without  effecting  substantial 
changes  in  the  principle  of  such  regulation.^** 

It  is  our  conclusion  from  a  study  of  the  decisions  construing  and 
applying  the  statute  that  the  failures  of  enforcement  cannot  be  fairly 
attributed  to  the  adoption  by  the  Supreme  Court  of  the  rule  of  reason. 
By  this  we  do  not  imply  that  there  have  not  been  rulings  which  have 
frustrated  the  statutory  purpose.  In  our  judgment,  such  a  rule, 
properly  understood  and  correctly  applied,  can  be  a  source  of  strength 
rather  than  of  weakness.  Some  rule  of  reason  was  inevitable.  A  law 
which  strait-jacketed  business  enterprise  would  fall  of  its  own  weight. 

We  turn  now  to  a  consideration  of  the  application  of  the  statute  to 
specific  acts  and  practices  of  trade  grou^ps,  from  which  a  fuller  under- 
standing of  the  meaning  of  the  rule  of  reason  can  be  derived. 

DIRECT  PRICE-FIXING 

(A)    ANALYSIS    OF    PRACTICE 

The  elimination  of  price  competition  in  any  industry,  trade,  or  line 
of  commerce  by  the  fixation  of  the  market  price  may  be  accomplished 
directly  by  agreement  or  understanding  among  competitors  or  in- 
directly by  various  devices,  methods,  and  practices.  We  shall  deal 
at  this  point  with  direct  price-fixing  by  agreement  or  understanding. 

A  distinction  must  be  drawn  between  the  fixation  of  the  market 
price  by  agreement  among  competitors  and  the  elimination  of  price 
competition  among  the  members  of  a  minority  group  not  having  the 
power  to  determine  the  market  price.  The  market  price  can  be 
established  by  agreement  only  where  sellers  or  buyers  controlling  a 
substantial  part  of  the  industry,  trade,  or  line  of  commerce,  participate 
in  the  combination.  Price-fixing  arrangements  eliminating  the  com- 
petition among  the  parties  thereto,  however,  are  frequently  made  h} 
minority  groups  which  are  not  in  control  of  the  market.  Such  agree- 
ments may  well  affect  the  market  price  even  though  they  do  not 
control  it. 


»«  See  United  States  v.  Socony-Vacuum  Oil  Co.  (1940),  310  U.  S.  150,  213,  218. 
291144 — 41 — No.  38 2 


IQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

-  Price-fixing  agreements  may  relate  to  the  establishment  of  uniform 
selling  prices,  bids,  or  offers,  to  the  maintenance  of  existing  price 
levels,  to  the  uniform  movement,  either  up  or  down,  of  the  prices  of 
competitors,  or  to  the  establishment  of  various  mechanisms  by  which 
the  prices  of  the  parties  to  the  agreement  are  determined.  An  agree- 
ment relating  to  the  movement  of  prices  is  nonetheless  a  price  agree- 
ment though  it  may  contemplate  the  uniform  reduction  rather  than 
the  increase  of  prices. 

(B)    EFFECTS    OF    PEACTICE 

The  price-fixing  agreement  is  the  least  costly  and  most  effective  of 
the  devices  by  which  competition  may  be  suppressed.  It  involves 
none  of  the  difficulties  of  the  merger  and  consolidation  and  yet  may  be 
virtually  as  efficacious  in  the  elimination  of  competition.  An  agree- 
ment fixing  market  prices  introduces  rigidity  into  that  portion  of  the 
price  structure  which  the  commodities  in  question  comprise  and  pre- 
vents the  flexible  adjustment  of  such  prices  to  fluctuations  in  supply 
and  demand. 

Whether  the  prices  fixed  are  reasonable  or  unreasonable,  the 
valuable  and  essential  quality  of  flexibility  and  the  advantages  of 
competition  are  destroyed  by  such  agreements.  With  the  accelerated 
tempo  of  modern  economic  change,  prices,  though  originally  reason- 
able, must  be  constantly  revised  if  they  are  to  continue  to  be  entirely 
fair.  Wlio  is  to  determine  the  fairness  of  the  prices  of  the  multitudinous 
commodities  that  swell  the  currents  of  interstate  commerce?  The 
public  obviously  cannot  rely  on  the  self-restraint  of  the  participants 
in  the  price-fixing  agreement.  Judicial  supervision  of  the  reasonable- 
ness of  prices  can  be  but  sporadic,  dependent  as  it  is  upon  the  un- 
certain and  fortuitous  course  of  litigation.  A  court  ruling  approving 
of  prices  today  is  no  warrant  that  the  prices  a  month  hence  will  be 
satisfactory,  and  only  by  new  litigation  that  may  endure  for  years 
can  a  supplemental  determination  be  obtained.  Apart  from  the 
inherent  difficulties  of  determining  the  elusive  issue  of  reasonableness, 
the  very  laxity  of  judicial  supervision  would  impel  more  pervasive 
regulation.  Private  price-fixing,  therefore,  would  inevitably  lead  to 
governmental  price-fixing. 

(C)    SUMMARY    OF    AUTHORITIES 

Both  in  its  early  and  its  recent  pronouncements,  the  Supreme  Court 
has  consistently  condemned  direct  price-fixing  as  an  unlawful  and 
unreasonable  restraint  of  trade. '^  Notwithstanding  its  categorical 
condemnation  of  the  practice  during  the  first  decade  of  the  statute's 
existence,'^  further  rulings  on  the  legality  of  direct  price  fixing  have 

's  United  Slates  v.  Socnny-Vaamm  Oil  Co.  (1940),  310  U.  S.  150;  United  States  v.  Trenton  Potteries  Co. 
(1927),  273  U.  S.  392;  United  States  v.  Trans-Missovri  Freight  Assn.  (1897),  166  U.  S.  290;  United  States  v. 
Joint  Trafflc  A.tsn.  (1898),  171  U.  S.  Wr,;  Addyston  Pipe  and  Steel  Co.  v.  United  States  (1899),  175  U.  S.  211; 
Swift  &  Co.  V.  United  States  (1905),  19f>  U.  S.  375:  Standard  Sanitary  Mfg.  Co.  v.  United  States  (1912),  226  U.  S. 
20;  F.  r  C.  V  Pacific  States  Paper  Trade  Assn.  (1927),  273  U.  S.  52. 

Bibliography:  JalTe  &  Tohriner,  The  LcsaHty  of  Price-Fixins  Agreements  (1932)  45  Harv.  L.  Rev.  1164; 
Peppin,  Price  Fixing  Agreements  Under  the  Anti-Trust  Law  (1940)  28  Calif.  L.  Rev.  297;  The  Rule  of  Reason 
in  Loose-Knit  Combinations  (1932),  32  Col.  L.  Rev.  291;  Ooodnovv,  Trade  Combinations  at  Common  Law 
(1912)  12  Pol.  Sci.  Quar.  212;  Allen,  Criminal  Con.spirapics  in  Re.straint  of  Trade  at  Common  Law  (1910) 
23  Harv.  L.  Rev.  531;  Pope,  The  Legal  Asi)ect  of  Monopoly  (1907)  20  Harv.  L.  Rev  167;  Watkins,  The 
Chance  in  Trust  Policy  fl922)  35  Harv.  L.  Rev.  815,  926;  Naujoks,  Monopolv  and  Restraintof  Trade  Under 
the  Sherman  Act  (1928)  4  Wis.  L.  Rev.  387  (1928),  5  id.  at  1;  Handler,  Trade  Association  Activities  For- 
bidden by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  C.  C.  H.  Trade  Regulation  Comments  No.  2,  July  1938;  Esch. 
Summaries  of  Federal  Trade  Commission  Cases  in  Restraint  of  Trade  (1938). 

'•  United  States  v.  Trans-Missouri  Freight  Assn.  (1897),  166  U.  S.  290. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  H 

been  sought  in  almost  every  subsequent  decade.  The  subject  received 
elaborate  consideration  in  1927  in  United  States  v.  Trenton  Potteries 
Co."  where  a  price-fixing  agreement  made  by  persons  manufacturing 
and  distributing  82  percent  of  the  vitreous  pottery  bathroom  fixtures 
produced  in  this  country  was  declared  unlawful.  In  submitting  the 
case  to  the  jury,  the  trial  court  charged  that  if  it  found  that  the  agree- 
ment alleged  in  the  indictment  had  been  made  by  the  defendants, 
it  might  return  a  verdict  of  guilty  without  regard  to  the  reasonableness 
of  the  prices  fixed  and  irrespective  of  whether  prices  were  actually 
lowered  or  raised,  since  a  price-fixing  agreement  in  and  of  itself  was 
an  unreasonable  restraint  of  trade.  It  refused  to  charge  the  jury,  as 
requested  by  the  defendants,  that  a  price-fixing  agreement  was 
invalid  only  if  the  prices  fixed  were  unreasonable.  The  pertinent 
passage  from  the  charge  is  as  follows: 

*  *  *  the  law  is  clear  that  an  agreement  on  the  part  of  the  members  of  a 
combination  controlling  a  substantial  part  of  an  industry,  upon  the  prices  which 
the  members  are  to  charge  for  their  commodity,  is  in  itself  an  undue  and  unreason- 
able restraint  of  trade  and  commerce;     *     *     *.'^ 

In  sustaining  this  charge,  the  Supreme  Court  said: 

*  *  *  But  it  does  not  follow  that  agreements  to  fix  or  maintain  prices  are 
reasonable  restraints  and  therefore  permitted  by  the  statute,  merely  because  the 
prices  themselves  are  reasonable.  Reasonableness  is  not  a  concept  of  definite 
and  unchanging  content.  Its  meaning  necessarily  varies  in  the  different  fields 
of  the  law,  because  it  is  used  as  a  convenient  summary  of  the  dominant  considera- 
tions which  control  in  the  application  of  legal  doctrines.  Our  view  of  what  is  a 
reasonable  restraint  of  commerce  is  controlled  by  the  recognized  purpose  of  the 
Sherman  Law  itself.  Whether  this  type  of  restraint  is  reasonable  or  not  must  be 
judged  in  part  at  least  in  the  light  of  its  effect  on  competition,  for  whatever 
difference  of  opinion  there  may  be  among  economists  as  to  the  social  and  economic 
desirability  of  an  unrestrained  competitive  system,  it  cannot  be  doubted  that  the 
Sherman  Law  and  the  judicial  decisions  interpreting  it  are  based  upon  the  assump- 
tion that  the  public  interest  is  best  protected  from  the  evils  of  monopoly  and  price 
control  by  the  maintenance  of  competition.     *     *     *.'^ 

After  a  full  review  of  its  prior  rulings  holding  direct  price  fixing  to 
be  invalid  per  se,  it  stated  its  conclusions  as  follows: 

The  aim  and  result  of  every  price-fixing  agreement,  if  effective,  is  the  elimina- 
tion of  one  form  of  competition.  The  power  to  fix  prices,  whether  reasonably 
exercised  or  not,  involves  power  to  control  the  market  and  to  fix  arbitrary  and 
unreasonable  prices.  The  reasonable  price  fixed  today  may  through  economic 
and  business  changes  become  the  unreasonable  price  of  tomorrow.  Once  estab- 
lished, it  may  be  maintained  unchanged  because  of  the  absence  of  competition 
secured  by  the  agreement  for  a  price  reasonable  when  fixed.  Agreements  which 
create  such  potential  power  may  well  be  held  to  be  in  themselves  unreasonable  or 
unlawful  restraints,  without  the  necessity  of  minute  inquiry  whether  a  particular 
price  is  reasonable  or  unreasonable  as  fixed  and  without  placing  on  the  Govern- 
ment in  enforcing  the  Sherman  Law  the  burden  of  ascertaining  from  day  to  day 
whether  it  has  become  unreasonable  through  the  mere  variation  of  economic 
conditions.  Moreover,  in  the  absence  of  express  legislation  requiring  it,  we 
should  hesitate  to  adopt  a  construction  making  the  difference  between  legal  and 
illegal  conduct  in  the  field  of  business  relations  depend  upon  so  uncertain  a  test 
as  whether  prices  are  reasonable — a  determination  which  can  be  satisfactorily 
made  only  after  a  complete  survey  of  our  economic  organization  and  a  choice 
between  rival  philosophies.^" 

The  Court  in  the  recent  case  of  United  States  v.  Socony-Vacuum 
Oil  Co.,^^  has  had  occasion  recently  to  reexamine  the  basis  of  its 

'7  (1927)  273  U.  S.  392.    Discussediin  (1927)  7  B.  U.  L.  Rev.  322;  (1927)  11  Marq.  L.  Rev.  163. 

«» ri927)  273  U.  S.  392,  396. 

i«  Id.  at  396. 

20  Id.  at  397. 

SI  (1940)  310  U.  S.  150. 


J  2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

decision  in  the  Trenton  Potteries  and  kindred  cases.  Not  only  has  it 
reaffirmed  the  Trenton  Potteries  ruling,  but  it  has  earnestly  endeavored 
to  plug  every  hole  that  may  have  existed  or  that  might  be  driven 
through  the  doctrine  of  that  case.  The  Court  restates  the  rule, 
after  a  careful  analysis  of  the  precedents,  as  follows: 

Thus  for  over  40  years  this  Court  has  consistently  and  without  deviation 
adhered  to  the  principle  that  price-fixing  agreements  are  unlawful  per  se  under 
the  Sherman  Act  and  that  no  showing  of  so-called  competitive  abuses  or  evils 
which  those  agreements  were  designed  to  eliminate  or  alleviate  may  be  interposed 
as  a  defense. ^2 

It  disposes  of  the  attempted  justifications  of  the  defendants'  acts 
in  the  following  unambiguous  terms: 

Ruinous  competition,  financial  disaster,  evils  of  price  cutting  and  the  like 
appear  throughout  our  history  as  ostensible  justifications  for  price-fixing.  If  the 
so-called  competitive  abuses  were  to  be  appraised  here,  the  reasonableness  of 
prices  would  necessarily  become  an  issue  in  every  price-fixing  case.  In  that 
event  the  Sherman  Act  would  soon  be  emasculated;  its  philosophy  would  be  sup- 
planted by  one  which  is  wholly  alien  to  a  system  of  free  competition;  it  would 
not  be  the  charter  of  freedom  which  its  framers  intended.     *     *     * 

Congress  has  not  left  with  us  the  determination  of  whether  or  not  particular 
price-fixing  schemes  are  wise  or  unwise,  healthy,  or  destructive.  It  has  not  per- 
mitted the  age-old  cry  of  ruinous  competition  and  competitive  evils  to  be  a 
defense  to  price-fixing  conspiracies.  It  has  no  more  allowed  genuine  or  fancied 
competitive  abuses  as  a  legal  justification  for  such  schemes  than  it  has  the  good 
intentions  of  the  members  of  the  combination.  If  such  a  shift  is  to  be  made,  it 
must  be  done  by  the  Congress.  Certainly  Congress  has  not  left  us  with  any  such 
choice.  Nor  has  the  act  created  or  authorized  the  creation  of  any  special  excep- 
tion in  favor  of  the  oil  industry.  Whatever  may  be  its  peculiar  problems  and 
characteristics,  the  Sherman  Act,  so  far  as  price-fixing  agreements  are  concerned, 
establishes  one  uniform  rule  applicable  to  all  industries  alike. ^^^ 

The  ambit  of  the  Trenton  Potteries  ^*  rule  is  thus  d.efined: 

Nor  is  it  important  that  the  prices  paid  by  the  combination  were  not  fixed  in 
the  sense  that  they  were  uniform  and  inflexible.  Price-fixing  as  used  in  the 
Trenton  Potteries  case  has  no  such  limited  meaning.  An  agreement  to  pay  or 
charge  rigid,  uniform  prices  would  be  an  illegal  agreement  under  the  Sherman 
Act.  But  so  would  agreements  to  raise  or  lower  prices  whatever  machinery  for 
price-fixing  was  used.  *  *  *  Hence,  prices  are  fixed  within  the  meanmg  of 
the  Trenton  Potteries  case  if  the  range  within  which  purchases  or  sales  will  be 
made  is  agreed  upon,  if  the  prices  paid  or  charged  are  to  be  at  a  certain  level  or 
on  ascending  or  descending  scales,  if  they  are  to  be  uniform,  or  if  by  various 
formulae  they  are  related  to  the  market  prices.  They  are  fixed  because  they  are 
agreed  upon.^^ 

In  order  to  avoid  any  misconception  of  its  holding,  the  Court  re- 
peats its  conclusions  as  follows: 

Under  the  Sherman  Act  a  combination  formed  for  the  purpose  and  with  the 
effect  of  raising,  depressing,  fixing,  pegging,  or  stabilizing  the  price  of  a  com- 
modity in  interstate  or  foreign  commerce  is  illegal  per  se.^^ 

Not  only  is  direct  price-fixing  a  violation  of  the  Sherman  law;  it  is 
an  unfair  method  of  competition  prohibited  by  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission  Act.^^  The  Federal  Trade  Commission  has  issued  nu- 
merous orders  forbidding  price-fixing  by  competitors.^^ 

The  reiterated  assertion  by  the  Court  in  decisions  rendered  after 
the  Trenton  Potteries  and  before  the  Socony-Vacuum  cases  that  there 

22  /(/.  at  218. 

23  Id.  at  221. 

2<  (1927)  27.3  U.  S.  392. 

»  Uiiited  States  v.  Soconp  Vacuum  Oil  Co.  (1940),  310  U.  S.  150,  222. 

26 /d.  at  223. 

2'  F.  T.  C.  V.  Pacific  States  Paper  Trade  Assn.  (1927),  273  U.  S.  52. 

2'  See  supra  n.  15. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  J  3 

must  ill  cveiy  case  be  "a  definite  factual  showing  of  illegality"  ^^ 
created  some  doubt  as  to  whether  such  factual  proof  might  be  neces- 
sary in  litigation  concerning  price-fixing.  All  such  doubts  were  dis- 
pelled by  the  Socoriy-Vacuum  decision  which  repeatedly  states  that 
the  practice  is  unlawful  per  ae  and  that  facts  purporting  to  justify 
it  are  of  no  avail. 

It  is  thus  possible,  in  light  of  these  unequivocal  pronouncements, 
to  state  without  qualification  the  present  doctrine  in  respect  of  price- 
fixing.  Any  agreement,  arrangement,  or  understanding  among  com- 
petitors, in  or  affecting  interstate  commerce,  fixing  the  market  price 
of  the  goods  which  they  sell  or  purchase,  is  unlawful  under  the  anti- 
trust laws.  It  matters  not  whether  the  prices  are  set  by  combinations 
of  sellers  or  buyers,  whether  prices  are  raised,  lowered,  or  maintained 
at  existmg  levels,  whether  the  prices  are  reasonable  or  unreasonable, 
whether  the  agreement  fixes  minimum  or  maximum  prices,  or  whether 
price  structures  are  tampered  with  by  direct  agreement  or  by  any 
other  means.  Nor  are  the  motives  or  intentions  of  the  members  of 
the  combination  material.  It  is  of  no  moment  that  they  may  in  good 
faith  have  regarded  such  an  agreement  as  essential  to  their  economic 
salvation.  Nor  would  evidence  be  admissible,  if  such  could  ever  be 
produced,  that  in  practice  the  agreement  resulted  in  demonstrable 
social  and  economic  benefits  to  all  those  in  or  dependent  upon  the 
industry  in  which  the  combination  operates.  The  fact  that  the 
agreement  fixes  or  maintains  prices  is  conclusive  of  its  illegality.  ^^ 

Wliile  the  court  in  the  Trenton  Potteries  case  stressed  the  fact  that 
the  defendants  controlled  82  percent  of  their  industry  and  stated  the 
rule  in  terms  of  price-fixing  "by  those  controlling  in  any  substantial 
manner  a  trade  or  business,"  it  had  no  occasion  to  and  it  did  not 
draw  any  distinction  between  price-fLxing  by  majority  and  minority 
groups.  Though  it  is  clear  that  a  minority  combination  whose  aim 
is  to  control  the  market  price  is  unlawful,  doubt  has  arisen  when  its 
purpose  is  not  to  fix  the  market  price  but  merely  to  eliminate  price 
competition  among  the  members  of  the  combination.  In  earlier  de- 
cisions, the  degree  of  market  control  was  not  deemed  a  material 
factor  in  determining  the  legality  of  any  arrangement  restrictive  of 
competition.^^  In  Appalachian  Coals,  Inc.,  v.  United  States, ^^  however, 
the  Court  upheld  an  exclusive  sales  agency  which  had  been  formed 
to  market  54.21  percent  of  the  coal  mined  in  the  Appalachian  area, 
notwithstanding  the  fact  that  the  arrangement  eliminated  competi- 
tion among  the  parties  thereto.  The  Court  emphasized  the  fact  that 
the  combination  was  subject  to  effective  competition  in  all  the  mar- 
kets in  which  its  products  were  disposed  and  that  the  defendants, 
consequently,  were  unable  to  control  the  market  price  of  their  coal. 

»9  Standard  Oil  Co.  (Indiana)  v.  U.  S.  (1931),  283  U.  S.  163,  179,  discussed  in  40  Yale  L.  J.  1297,  31  Col. 
L.  Rev.  1049;  Appalachian  Coals,  Inc.,  v.  United  States  (1933),  288  U.  S.  344,  377,  discussed  in  Eldridge,  The 
Appalachian  Coals  Case  and  the  Rule  of  Reason  (1933),  1  Geo.  Wash.  L.  Rev.  507  (1933),  31  Mich.  L.  Rev. 
837  (1933),  28  III.  L.  Rev.  265  (193.3),  19  Va.  L.  Rev.  851  (1933),  81  U.  of  Pa.  L.  Rev.  lOOfi. 

30  For  recent  consent  decrees  prohibiting  price-fl.\ine,  see:  United  States  v.  National  Assn.  of  Commission 
Lumber  Salesmen,  C.  0.  H.  Trade  Reg.  Serv.  (8th  ed/)  par.  25,414  (E.  D.  La.  1940);  United  Slates  v.  Engi- 
neering Survey  and  Audit  Co.,  Inc.,  id.  par.  25,415  (E.  D.  La.  1940);  United  States  v.  Pittstjurgh  Tile  and  Mantel 
Contractors'  Assn.,  id.  par.  25,417  (W.  D.  Pa.  1940);  United  States  v.  Employing  Plasterers'  Assn.  of  Allegheny 
County,  id.  par.  25,429  (W.  D.  Pa.  1940);  United  States  v.  Underwood  PUIiott  Fisher  Company,  id.  par.  25, ASS 
(S.  D.  N.  Y.  1940);  United  States  v.  National  Container  Assn.,  id.  par.  25,4.34  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  1940);  United  States 
v.  American  Potash  and  Chemical  Corp.,  id.  par.  25,461  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  1940);  United  States  v.  The  Tile  Con- 
tractors' A.?sn.  of  America,  id.  par.  25,469  (N.  D.  111.  1940);  United  States  v.  Long  Island  Sand  and  Gravel 
Producers'  Assn.,  id.  par.  25,475  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  1940);  United  States  v.  liausch  &  tomb  Optical  Co.,  id.  par. 
25,487  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  1940);  United  Slates  v.  The  Borden  Co.,  id.  par.  25,520  (N.  D.  111.  1940);  United  States  v. 
Southern  California  Marble  Assn.,  id.  par.  25,607  (S.  D.  Calif.  1940);  United  States  v.  Electrical  Solderleas 
Service  Connector  Institute,  id.  par.  25,585  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  1941). 

31  Addvston  Pipe  &  Steel  Co.  v.  United  States  (1899),  175  U.  S.  211;  American  Column  &  Lumber  Co.  v. 
United  States  (1921),  257  U.  S.  377. 

3»  (1933)  288  U.  S.  344. 


2^4  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Further  support  for  the  view  that  the  Court  might  permit  price- 
fixing  by  minority,  nonmonopoly  groups,  was  afforded  in  Standard 
Oil  Co.  {Indiana)  v.  United  States.^^  Tliere  the  fixation  of  royalty 
rates  as  part  of  a  cross-hcensing  arrangement  of  competing  patents 
was  sustained  on  the  ground  that  the  gasohne  produced  by  the 
patented  cracking  process  competed  with  the  gasohne  made  by  un- 
patented methods  and  that  the  proportion  of  cracked  gas  sold  was 
too  slight  to  have  any  effect  on  the  ultimate  price  of  gasohne  to 
consumers. 

However,  in  the  recent  Socony-Vacuum.  ^*  case,  the  Court  in  a  strong 
dictum  declared  price-fixing  by  groups  without  the  power  to  control 
the  market  to  be  unlawful  as  constituting  a  "threat  to  the  central 
nervous  system  of  the  economy".^^  It  would  thus  appear  that  the 
contrary  intimations  of  the  Appalachian  ^^  and  the  Cracking  ^''  cases 
have  been  definitely  rejected  and  that  under  the  present  construction 
of  the  statute  no  price  agreements  between  two  or  more  competitors 
will  be  tolerated. 

The  degree  of  market  control  possessed  by  a  combination  is  an 
element  of  such  importance  in  antitrust  litigation  that  we  shall  re- 
turn, in  a  later  section  of  this  study,  to  a  more  detailed  consideration 
of  this  factor. 

CONTROL  OF  OUTPUT 

(a)  analysis  of  practice 

The  regulation  of  output  is  almost  as  effective  an  instrument  for 
the  suppression  of  competition  as  direct  price-fixing  and  may  in  fact 
be  one  of  the  methods  by  which  prices  are  regulated.  Such  control 
may  be  exerted  by  formal  agreement  or  by  mere  informal  understand- 
ing. In  equating  supply  with  probable  demand,  hours  of  plant  oper- 
ation may  be  limited,  complete  shut-downs  may  be  ordered  or  business 
allocated  among  producers  on  the  basis  of  some  predetermined  quota. 

Output  control  sometimes  has  for  its  object  not  the  regulation  of 
prices  but  the  solution  of  problems  created  by  excess  capacity.  Wliat- 
ever  its  object,  the  private  control  of  production  definitely  tends  to 
eliminate  and  restrict  competition. 

The  regulation  of  output  does  not  necessarily  imply  its  ciu"tailment. 
Production  may  be  maintained  at  an  agreed  level  or  actually  increased. 
The  true  test  is  not  whether  output  is  in  fact  reduced,  but  whether 
it  is  determined  by  the  concerted  and  cooperative  action  of  competitors 
rather  than  by  the  normal  operation  of  competitive  forces. 

(b)  state  of  the  authorities 

There  are  not  as  many  reported  cases  involving  the  control  of 
production  as  there  are  involving  direct  price-fixing.^^     It  is  indeed 

M  (1931)  283  U.  S.  163. 

3<  (1940)  310  U.  S.  150. 

35  Id.  at  224,  n.  59. 

30  (1933)  288  U.  S.  344. 

"  (1931)  283  U.  S.  163. 

39  See  American  Column  &  TAimber  Co.  v.  United  States  (1921),  257  U.  S.  377;  Oibbit  v.  McNedey  (C.  C.  A. 
9th,  1902),  118  Fed.  120;  United  States  v.  National  Assn.  of  Window  Glass  Mfrs.  (1923),  263  U.  S.'403;  Conti- 
nental Wall  Paper  Co.  v.  Lewis  Voigtit  &  Sons  Co.  (C.  C.  A.  6th,  1906),  148  Fed.  939,  947,  affirmed  (1909), 
212  U.  S.  227;  Cravens  v.  Carter-Crnme  Co.  (C.  C.  A.  6th,  1899),  92  Fed.  479,  481,  485.  For  a  recent  consent 
decree  prohibitinp  the  hmitation  of  output  see  United  States  v.  National  Container  Assn.,  C.  C.  H.  Trade- 
Eeg.  Serv.  (8th  ed.)  par.  25,434  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  1940). 

Bibliography:  qnie  Rule  of  Reason  in  Loose-Knit  Combinations  (1932),  32  Col.  L.  Rev.  291,  305;  Handler, 
The  Susar  Institute  Case  and  the  Present  Status  of  the  Anti-Trust  Laws  (1936),  36  Col.  L.  Rev.  1,  21; 
Handler,  Trade  Association  Activities  Forbidden  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  C.  C.  H.  Trade 
Regulation  Comments  No.  2,  July  1938;  Burns,  The  Decline  of  Competition  (1936),  64,  154. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  15 

curious  that  on  a  problem  of  such  paramount  importance  there  should 
be  such  a  paucity  of  authoritative  rulings.  Such  decisions  as  there 
are  indicate  quite  clearly  that  any  concerted  effort  to  regulate  pro- 
duction contravenes  the  antitrust  laws.  In  American  Column  &  Lum- 
ber- Co.  V.  United  States,^^  an  association  of  hardwood  manufacturers, 
whose  members  were  responsible  for  about  one-third  of  the  national 
output,  sought  by  an  elaborate  program  of  trade  statistics  and  the 
suggestions  and  exhortations  of  its  statistical  manager  to  limit  pro- 
duction. The  Supreme  Court  declared  the  activities  of  the  associa- 
tion to  be  unlawful,  emphasizing  the  illegal  nature  of  the  manager's 
efforts  to  discourage  a  threatened  "overproduction"  in  the  industry. 
This  ruling  was  preceded  by  the  decision  of  the  circuit  court  of  appeals 
in  Gibbs  v.  McNeeley  *"  in  wliich  a  combination  of  manufacturers  and 
wholesalers  of  red-cedar  sliingles  agreed  to  fix  prices  and  to  shut  down 
their  mills  or  take  other  necessary  steps  to  curtail  output  whenever 
supply  exceeded  demand.     The  Court  stated: 

The  combination  in  the  case  before  the  court  is  more  than  a  combination  to 
regulate  prices;  it  is  a  combination  to  control  the  production  of  a  manufactured 
article  more  than  four-fifths  of  which  is  made  for  interstate  trade,  and  to  diminish 
competition  in  its  production,  as  well  as  to  advance  its  price.  These  features, 
we  think,  determine  its  object,  and  bring  it  under  the  condemnation  of  the 
law." 

In  National  Assn.  of  Window  Glass  Mfrs.  v.  United  States  *^  the 
Supreme  Court  upheld  an  arrangement  whereby  the  available  labor 
supply  in  the  handblown  window-glass  industry  was  divided  among 
all  manufacturers  in  such  manner  as  to  permit  each  producer  to  oper- 
ate liis  plant  at  full  capacity  during  a  part  of  the  year  and  to  shut 
down  his  mill  the  remainder  of  the  year.  Workers  were  shifted  from 
one  group  of  plants  to  the  other  at  the  end  of  each  period.  The  effect 
of  the  agreement  was  to  reduce  overhead  costs  and  to  provide  con- 
tinuity of  employment  for  workers  in  the  industry.  The  handblown 
product  was  marketed  in  competition  wdth  machine-made  glass  and 
comprised  but  a  minor  part  of  the  output  of  the  wdndow-glass  industry. 

The  import  of  this  decision  is  not  that  limitation  of  production  may 
be  justified  under  special  conditions  or  that  minority  groups  in  an 
industry  are  privileged  to  regulate  their  output.  The  Court  ap- 
parently agreed  with  the  defendant's  assertion  that  the  arrangement 
did  not  lessen  output.    Thus,  it  states: 

From  the  view  that  we  take  we  think  it  unnecessary  to  *  *  *  do  more 
than  advert  to  the  defendants'  contention  that  with  the  means  available  the 
production  is  increased.^* 

The  basis  of  decision  was  that  the  limited  labor  supply  did  not  permit 
all  plants  to  be  fully  manned  during  the  entire  year.     A  factory  oper- 
ating at  full  capacity  for  part  of  the  year,  the  Court  felt,  would 
produce  approximately  the  same  as  one  operating  at  partial  capacity 
for  the  entire  year.     The  case  dealt  with  a  dying  industry  and  an 
abnormal  industrial  situation.     The  decision  has  been  strictly  lim- 
ited to  its  facts  and  has  not  been  regarded  as  an  authoritative  prec- 
edent on  the  question  of  production  limitation.     As  the  combination 
condemned  in  the  Column  &  Lumber  *^  case  was  a  minority  non- 
39  (1921)  257  U.  S.  377. 
"  (C.  C.  A.  9th,  1902)  118  Fed.  120. 
"  Id.  at  127. 
<2  (1923)  263  U.  S.  403. 
«  Id.  at  413. 
"  (1921)  257  U.  S.  377. 


IQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

monopolistic  group,  the  Window  Glass  *^  case  can  hardly  be  con- 
strued as  upholding  output  curbs  by  minority  groups. ^^ 

The  Federal  Trade  Commission  has  dealt  with  agreements  to  con- 
trol output  involving  the  use  of  a  quota  system  and  compulsory 
shutdowns.  In  accord  with  the  rulings  of  the  Supreme  Court,  the 
Commission  has  held  such  arrangements  unlawful.*^  Consent  decrees 
have  been  entered  forbidding  arrangements  designed  to  control  the 
output  of  various  industries.^* 

There  does  not  appear  to  be  any  clear  authority  involving  con- 
certed increases  or  other  regulations  of  production.  The  decided 
cases  have  all  involved  curtailments.  There  is,  however,  nothing  in 
the  decisions  which  would  support  the  view  that  only  arrangements 
which  limit  output  are  forbidden  by  the  antitrust  laws.  Under  the 
ratio  decidendi  of  the  price-fixing  cases,  it  would  appear  that  any  inter- 
ference with  the  equation  of  supply  and  demand  by  the  normal  opera- 
tion of  competitive  forces  would  be  condemned. 

(C)    SUGGESTIONS 

Private  output  control  is  inconsistent  with  the  maintenance  of 
competition  and,  like  price-fixing,  cannot  be  tolerated  in  any  economy 
dedicated  to  free  competition.  The  economic  efi^ects  of  private  regu- 
lation of  output  are  the  same  as  price-fixing.  The  same  objections, 
economic  and  administrative,  apply  to  both,  and  as  they  have  been 
fully  expressed  in  the  section  on  direct  price-fixing,  they  need  not  be 
here  repeated. 

That  excess  capacity  and  the  tendency  of  many  mdustries  to  over- 
produce raise  serious  economic  problems  cannot  be  denied.  But  a 
solution  of  such  problems  is  not  to  be  found  in  any  industrial  policy 
which  destroys  competition  and  vests  dictatorial  control  of  vital 
industrial  processes  in  the  hands  of  a  lunited  number  of  business 
managers.  A  statistical  program,  which  will  educate  and  enlighten 
the  industrial  producer  and  the  coordination  and  analysis  of  statistics 
by  a  proper  agency  of  government,  will  aid  business  m  avoiding  the 
accumulation  of  unassimilable  surpluses  and  uneconomic  fluctuations 
in  the  volume  of  production.  Adjustment  of  supply  to  demand 
through  competitive  forces,  guided  by  wise  governmental  suggestion 
and  advice  and  informed  by  accurate  trade  data,  is  to  be  preferred  to 
private  and  unsupervised  control  of  tlie  vital  policies  of  mdustrial 
output. 

In  view  of  the  above  considerations,  all  agreements  among  competi- 
tors relating  to  the  control  of  production  should  be  held  unlawful, 
regardless  of  the  purpose  of  such  agreements  and  regardless  of  the 
degree  of  market  control  possessed  by  the  members  of  the  combination. 

SHARING  MARKETS 

(a)  analysis  of  practice 

Competitors,  fearful  of  the  consequences  of  unrestricted  price 
competition  and  eager  to  establish  competitive  stability,  may  seek  to 
accomplish  their  purpose  by  sharing  markets  rather  than  by  resorting 

<«  (1923)  263  U.  S.  403. 

"  See  also  Chesapeake  &  Ohio  Fuel  Co.  v.  United  States  (C.  C.  A.  6th,  1902),  115  Fed.  610. 

"  See  California  Rice  Industry,  106  0.  C.  H.  1938  Trade  Reg.  Serv.,  par.  9431;  Tarpon  Springs  Sponge 
Exchange,  Inc.,  106  C.  C.  H.  1938  Trade  Ree.  Serv.,  par.  9309. 

"  United  States  v.  Maine  Cooperative  Sardine  Co.  (D.  Me.,  Mav  16,  1927);  see  Donovan  &  McAllister, 
Consent  Decrees  in  the  Enforcement  of  Federal  Anti-Trust  Laws  (1933)  46  Harv.  L.  Rev.  885,  926. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  17 

to  direct  price-fixing.  Slmring  the  market  may  consist  in  allocating 
fixed  percentages  of  the  available  business  to  each  producer,  dividing 
sales  territory  on  a  geographical  basis  or  allotting  customers  to  each 
seller.  By  restrictions  upon  the  hours  of  plant  operation,  markets 
may  be  shared  on  the  basis  of  productive  capacity.  Business  may 
also  be  distributed  through  a  common  sales  agency  which  ordinarily 
has  the  power  either  to  impose  production  quotas  on  its  members  or 
apportion  orders  among  them. 

Wlien  products  are  not  homogeneous  or  when  each  producer  manu- 
factures a  variety  of  products,  price  control  may  not  be  a  feasible 
method  of  regulation  and  market  division  may  be  the  only  practicable 
means  of  controlling  competition.  Each  competitor  will  then  receive 
his  share  of  the  business  and  no  more.  The  policy  is  essentially  one 
of  "live  and  let  live."  The  effect  of  any  agreement  for  sharing  the 
markets  is  manifestly  to  eliminate  competition. 

Prices,  under  such  circumstances,  tend  to  be  uniform  except  as 
products  differ  or  are  marketed  under  conditions  permitting  differences 
in  price  without  disturbing  the  desired  allocation  of  business.  If  there 
is  not  complete  uniformity  of  price,  the  prices  of  different  producers 
must  nevertheless  maintain  the  same  relative  position  to  each  other 
that  they  had  when  the  markets  were  first  divided.  Flexibility  and 
freedom  in  the  response  of  prices  to  economic  changes  are  lost.  Mar- 
kets may  be  shared  at  any  level  of  prices  and  the  tendency  is  for  prices 
to  be  higher  than  when  competition  is  left  unrestrained. 

Any  distribution  of  business  necessarily  limits  output,  increases 
costs,  and  constricts  firms  capable  of  expansion.  The  least  efficient 
producers  are  protected  and  the  advantages  of  a  less  costly  method  of 
distribution  and  production  are  lost  to  the  public. 

(b)  summary  of  authorities 

Recognizing  the  dangers  implicit  in  these  arrangements,  the  Supreme 
Court  has  held  that  agreements  and  arrangements  for  sharing  mar- 
kets are  illegal  under  the  Sherman  Act.^^  The  rule  of  the  Addyston 
Pipe  ^°  case  has  been  consistently  followed  by  the  lower  Federal 
courts. ^^  The  Federal  Trade  Commission  has  adhered  to  these  court 
rulings  and  has  condemned  sharing  the  market  either  by  division  of 
territories  or  the  allocation  of  customers.^^ 

In  view  of  the  hostility  manifested  toward  the  cognate  devices  of 
price-fixing  and  production  control,  there  is  no  prospect  of  the  courts' 
countenancing  the  sharing  of  markets  by  agreement  or  understanding. 
There  is  thus  no  need  for  any  legislative  change  in  this  regard. 

"  Addyston  Pipe  &  Steel  Co.  v.  United  States  (1899),  175  U.  S.  211. 

'0  It)id. 

M  United  States  v.  MacAndrews  &  Forbes  Co.  (C.  C.  S.  D.  N.  Y.  1906),  149  Fed.  823;  Lee  Line  Steamers, 
Inc.,  V.  Memphis,  H.  &  R.  Packet  Co.  (C.  C.  A.  6th,  1922),  277  Fed.  5;  Butchart  v.  United  States  (C.  C.  A. 
9th,  1924),  295  Fed.  577.  For  recent  consent  decrees  prohibiting  the  sharing  of  markets  see:  United  States  v. 
National  Container  Assn.,  C.  C.  H.  Trade  Reg.  Serv.  (8th  ed.)  par.  25,434  (S.  D.N.  Y.  1940);  United  States  v . 
Long  Island  Sand  &  Gravel  Producers'  Asfn.,  id.  par.  25,475  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  1940);  United  States  v.  Bausch  & 
Lomb  Optical  Co.,  id.  par.  25,487  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  1940);  United  States  v.  Southern  California  Marble  Assn.,  id. 
par.  25,607  (S.  D.  Calif.  1940). 

Bibliography:  (1932)  32  Col.  L.  Rev.  291,  305;  Matthews  and  Adler,  Covenants  in  Restraint  of  Trade 
(2d  ed.  1907),  126-131;  Sanderson,  Rastraint  of  Trade  in  English  Law  (1926),  64-67;  Peppin,  Price-Fixing 
Agreements  Under  the  Sherman  Anti-Trust  Law  (1940).  28  Calif.  L.  Rev.  297,  300. 

'"  Washington  Cereal  Assn.,  11  F.  T.  C.  D.  396  (1937);  West  Coast  Theatres,  Inc.,  12  F.  T.  C.  D.  383  (1929); 
Lindsay  Light  Co.,  18  F.  T.  C.  D.  240  (1934);  Albany  Billiard  Ball  Co  ,  13  F.  T.  C.  D.  291  (1930);  Fyr-Fyter 
Co.,  21  F.  T.  C.  D.  257  (1935);  Linen  Supply  Assn.,  21  F.  T,  0.  D.  666  (1935). 


Ig  CONCETs^TRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

COLLECTION  AND  DISSEMINATION  OF  TRADE 
STATISTICS  AND  OPEN  PRICE  SYSTEMS 

(A)    DESCRIPTION    OF    PRACTICE 

The  collection  and  dissemination  of  trade  statistics  is  one  of  the 
important  activities  of  many  modern  trade  associations.  The  infor- 
mation which  is  gathered  varies  in  accordance  with  the  pm-poses 
and  needs  of  the  association.  The  principal  topics  on  which  infor- 
mation is  systematically  collected  are  prices,  plant  capacity,  volume 
of  production,  cost  of  production,  inventories,  transportation  costs, 
shipments,  deliveries,  sales,  unfilled  orders,  goods  in  transit,  terms 
and  conditions  of  sale,  and  other  data  of  a  similar  nature. 

The  price  information  which  is  collected  by  an  association  may 
relate  to  past,  current,  or  future  prices.  In  some  instances,  the 
price  lists  of  each  member  of  the  group  may  be  filed  with  the  associa- 
tion, immediate  notice  being  given  of  all  changes.  Some  associations 
merely  require  members  to  make  weekly  or  monthly  reports  of  their 
past  prices.  Under  other  plans  members  are  obliged  to  communicate 
by  telephone  the  full  details  of  each  sale  as  soon  as  it  is  concluded. 
The  filing  of  current  or  future  prices  may  involve  certain  collateral 
requirements  on  the  part  of  the  members  of  the  combination.  These 
supplementary  matters  may  include  any  or  all  of  the  following: 
(1)  Agreements  by  members  to  adhere  to  the  filed  prices  for  a  certain 
period  of  time;  (2)  agreements  by  members  not  to  deviate  from  the 
filed  prices  until  the  combination  is  apprised  of  a  change;  (3)  a  waiting 
period  before  the  announced  price  change  becomes  effective. 

There  are  similar  diversities  with  regard  to  the  nature  and  extent 
of  the  information  assembled  on  production,  sales,  inventories,  deliv- 
eries, and  the  like.  The  data  may  vary  from  detailed  reports  of  each 
transaction  to  general  weeldy  or  monthly  summaries. 

There  is  no  uniformity  of  practice  with  regard  to  the  information 
disseminated  by  an  association.  Some  associations  circulate  the 
reports  filed  by  members  without  change  or  comment;  others  distribute 
general  summaries,  which,  however,  are  suflEiciently  detailed  to  reveal 
the  price,  production,  and  business  policies  of  each  reporting  member; 
still  others  content  themselves  with  the  distribution  of  abstract  sta- 
tistical summaries  which  give  no  clue  to  the  individual  activities, 
practices,  and  policies  of  members. 

The  information  which  is  disseminated  may  be  restricted  to  members 
of  the  combination  or  it  may  be  made  available  to  the  purchasing  trade 
or  to  the  public  generally.  It  may  be  accompanied  by  interpretative 
comments  or  suggestions  with  regard  to  the  use  of  the  material  or  by 
exhortations  to  follow  a  recommended  course  of  action. 

The  program  may  be  supplemented  by  periodic  meetings  of  members 
at  which  discussions  may  vary  from  minute  consideration  of  the  price 
and  production  policies  of  individual  members  to  general  observations 
concerning  the  status  and  problems  of  the  industry.  The  plan  may  be 
implemented  by  penalties  for  nonobservance  of  its  requirements. 

There  are  manifold  permutations  of  trade  association  statistical 
programs.  As  some  features  are  added  or  modified  and  others  sub- 
tracted, the  legal  status  of  the  combination's  program  may  change. 
The  competitive  texture  of  the  industry  and  prior  industrial  practice, 
the  effects  of  the  program  on  competition,  the  economic  results 
achieved  through  the  exchange  of  information,  are  all  matters  of  im- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  JQ 

portance  in  determining  the  validity  of  a  particular  plan.  Here  we  can 
merely  enumerate  the  general  outlines  of  a  statistical  program ;  legality, 
however,  depends  upon  the  specific  contents  of  an  individual  plan  and 
its  potential  and  actual  effects  upon  competition. 

(b)  summary  of  authorities 

Apart  from  the  cases  dealing  with  direct  price-fixing,  there  are 
only  five  decisions  ^^  of  the  Supreme  Court  passing  upon  the  legality 
of  the  statistical  activities  of  trade  associations.  The  programs  in- 
volved in  these  cases  were  very  elaborate,  as  appears.  Three  of  the 
plans  were  held  to  constitute  unlawful  restramts  of  trade  and  two  were 
upheld.  The  Court  has  not  purported  in  these  cases  to  pass  upon  the 
validity  of  the  component  elements  of  these  programs  by  themselves 
■and  apart  from  the  plan  as  a  whole.  Its  decisions  have  been  limited 
to  the  legality  of  the  arrangements  in  their  entirety  although  there 
are  occasional  references  to  the  illegality  of  the  several  features  of  a 
complex  plan. 

The  component  parts  of  the  plan  have  been  treated  as  evidentiary 
of  ultimate  purposes  and  effects.  The  entu^e  plan  has  been  scrutinized 
to  determine  whether  it  has  resulted  or  is  likely  to  result  in  the  elimi- 
nation of  competition.  The  ultimate  question  in  every  case  has  been 
whether  it  can  fairly  be  said  that  implicit  in  the  plan  is  an  agreement 
or  understanding  with  regard  to  the  price  or  production  policy  to  be 
pursued  by  the  members  of  the  combination,  or  whether  there  is  an 
agreement  or  understanding  otherwise  restrictive  of  competition.  The 
fact  that  uniformity  of  prices  has  resulted  from  the  operation  of  the 
plan  has  not  been  deemed  conclusive  of  illegality.  Nor  has  the  Court 
given  much  weight  to  proof  that  the  motives  of  the  members  of  the 
combination  have  been  beneficent,  that  there  has  been  no  sinister 
purpose  or  abuse  of  economic  power,  or  that  the  objectives  of  the  plan 
may  have  been  economically  justifiable. 

The  generality  of  these  decisions,  the  primacy  given  to  the  facts,  and 
the  studied  refusal  of  the  Com"t  to  formulate  any  generalizations 
applicable  to  other  states  of  facts,  have  limited  their  practical  value  to 
those  interested  in  discovering  the  permissive  limits  of  the  statistical 
activities  of  trade  associations.  Uncertainty  is  not  removed  by  a 
doctrine  which  makes  each  case  a  law  unto  itself. 

The  Federal  Trade  Commission  in  numerous  proceedings  has  scruti- 
nized the  statistical  activities  of  trade  associations.  The  many  orders 
are  patterned  after  the  rulings  of  the  Supreme  Court  and  hence  need 
not  be  reviewed  here.^^* 

(C)    ENUMERATION  OF  IMPORTANT  FEATURES  OF  STATISTICAL  PROGRAMS 

Notwithstanding  the  difficulty  and  danger  involved  in  the  formula- 
tion of  any  generalization  with  regard  to  the  legality  of  the  component 
elements  of  any  statistical  program,  it  is  essential  that  this  be  done, 
if  any  sound  basis  for  prediction  is  to  be  established. 

'''American  Column  &  Lumber  Co.  v.  United  States,  (1921)  257  U.  S.  377,  discussed  in  (1922)  22  Col.  L 
Rev.  377,  (1922)  31  Yale  L.  J.  643,  (1922)  10  Calif.  L.  Rev.  350,  (1922)  20  Mich.  L.  Rev.  901;  United  States  v. 
American  Linseed  Oil  Co.,  (1923)  262  U.  S.  371,  discassed  in  (1924)  9  St.  Louis  L.  Rev.  67;  Maple  Flooring 
Mfrs.  Assn.  v.  United  States,  (1925)  268  U.  S.  563,  discussed  in  (1920)  20  111.  L.  Rev.  505,  (1925)  10  Minn. 
L.  Rev.  71,  (1925)  11  Corn.  L.  Q.  123,  (192.5)  11  A.  B.  A.  J.  422:  Cement  Mfrs.  Protective  Assn.  v.  United 
States,  (1925)  268  U.  S.  588,  discussed  in  (1925)  11  A.  B.  A.  J.  422,  (1926)  24  Mich.  L.  Rev.  316,  (1926)  20  111. 
L.  Rev.  505;  Suaar  Institute,  Inc.,  v.  United  States,  (1936)  297  U.  S.  553,  discussed  in  (1934)  43  Yale  L.  J., 
1295,  (1936")  31  111.  L.  Rev.  118,  (1936)  34  Mich.  L.  Rev.  1016. 

"a  Handler,  Trade  Association  Activities  forbidden  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  C.  C.  H.  Trade 
Hegulation  Comments  No.  2,  July  1938. 


20  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  principal  features  of  a  statistical  program  which  may  affect  its 
legality  are — 

(a)  Availability  to  purchasers  and  the  public  generally,  as  well 
as  to  members  of  the  association,  of  the  information  col- 
lected and  disseminated; 

(6)  The  collection  and  dissemination  of  information  relating  to 
closed  and  past  transactions; 

(c)  The  collection  and  dissemination  of  information  relating  to 

current  and  future  prices; 

(d)  Agreement  by  members  to  adhere  to  filed  prices  for  a  period 

of  time  or  not  to  deviate  therefrom  without  prior  notice; 

(e)  A  waiting  period  before  the  announced  price  change  becomes 

effective ; 

(J)  Full  disclosure  of  the  price,  production,  and  other  trade 
policies  of  each  member; 

(g)  Circulation  of  interpretative  comments  by  the  association; 

(h)  Discussion  of  the  price  and  production  policies  of  the  members 
of  the  combination; 

(i)  Recommendations  to,  persuasion  of,  or  pressure  upon  a  mem- 
ber of  the  combination  concerning  his  price  or  production 
policies; 

(j)  Penalties  for  the  nonobservance  of  the  requirements  of  the 
program. 

We  shall  consider  the  effect  of  each  of  these  factors  on  competition 
and  seek  to  appraise  the  weight  to  be  accorded  their  presence  or 
absence  in  determining  the  legality  of  a  statistical  program.  A  con- 
sideration of  the  possible  economic  desirability  of  those  features  that 
are  incompatible  with  a  competitive  regime  falls  outside  the  scope  of 
this  inquiry. 

(D)     APPRAISAL    OF    THE    LEGALITY    OF    THE    PRINCIPAL     FEATURES    OF 
STATISTICAL  PROGRAMS  ^* 

(1)  Nonavailability  to  purchasers  and  the  public  of  the  information 
collected  and  disseminated. — The  fact  that  an  association  confines  the 
circulation  of  the  information  collected  by  it  to  its  members,  without 
making  it  available  to  purchasers  or  giving  it  any  general  publicity, 
may  render  its  entire  statistical  program  unlawful.  In  both  American 
Column  &  Lumber  Co.  v.  United  States^^  and  United  States  v.  American 
Linseed  Oil  Co.,^^  the  Court  stressed  the  absence  of  such  publicity, 
althougli  the  decisions  were  not  placed  on  this  ground.  In  Maple 
Flooring  Mfrs.  Assn.  v.  United  States,^''  the  Court  emphasized  the 
fact  that  the  statistical  data  had  been  given  wide  pubhcity,  but  it 

"  BiblioKraphy:  Oliphant,  Trade  Associations  and  the  Law  (1926)  26  Col.  L.  Rev.  381;  Handler.  The 
Sugar  Institute  Case  and  the  Present  Status  of  the  Anti-Trust  Laws  (1936)  36  Col.  L.  Rev.  1;  Handler, 
Trade  Association  Activities  Forbidden  by  Federal  Trade  Commission,  C.  C.  H.  Trade  Regulation  Com- 
ments No.  2,  July  1938;  Fly,  Observations  on  the  Anti-Trust  Laws,  Economic  Theory  and  the  Sugar  Insti- 
tute Decisions  (1930)  4.'^  Yale  L.  J .  1.339,  46  id.  228,  Donovan,  The  Effect  of  the  Decision  in  the  Sugar  Institute 
Case  upon  Trade  Association  Activities  (1936)  84  U.  of  Pa.  L.  Rev.  929;  Uolbrook,  Price  Reporting  as  a 
Trade  Association  Activity,  1925  to  1935  (1935)  35  Col.  L.  Rev.  1053;  Sharfman,  The  Trade  Association 
Movement  (1926)  16  Am.  Econ.  Rev.  Supp.  203;  Henderson,  Statistical  Activities  of  Trade  Associations 
(1926)  id.  219;  Chaphn,  The  Collection  and  Distribution  of  Statistical  Information  by  Trade  Associations 
(1922)  7  St.  Louis  L.  Rev.  16;  Federal  Trade  Commission,  Open-Price  Trade  Associations  (1929),  containing 
suggestions  and  recommendations;  Esch,  Summaries  of  Federal  Trade  Commission  Cases  in  Restraint  of 
Trade  (1938);  N.  R.  A.  Office  Memo.  No.  228  (June  8,  1934);  N.  R.  A.  Release  No.  11056  (April  24,  1935); 
Kirsh,  Trade  Associations  in  Law  and  Business  (1938);  Lyon  &  Abramson,  The  Economics  of  Open  Price 
Systems  (1936). 

"(1921)  257  U.S.  377,  411. 

"(1923)  262  U.  S.  371,380. 

"  (1925)  268  U.  S.  563,  573. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  21 

did  not  predicate  its  ruling  on  this  fact  alone.  The  opinion  in  Cement 
Mfrs.  Protective  Assn.  v.  United  States '^^  does  not  disclose  the  extent 
of  the  publicity,  if  any,  accorded  the  association's  statistics. 

United  States  v.  Sugar  Institute,  Itic.,^^  is  the  hrst  case  in  which  an 
attempt  was  made  to  indicate  the  precise  legal  effect  of  the  absence 
of  publicity.  The  lower  court, ^^  in  forbidding  the  dissemination  of 
any  information  unless  it  was  made  available  to  the  purchasing  and 
distributing  trade,  indicated  that  the  restriction  of  the  information 
to  the  members  of  the  combine  was  in  itself  an  unreasonable  restraint 
of  trade.  The  Supreme  Court  modified  the  decree  so  far  as  it  required 
the  disclosure  of  confidential  material,  stating:  "Information  may  be 
received  in  relation  to  the  affairs  of  refiners  which  may  rightly  be 
treated  as  having  a  confidential  character  and  in  which  distributors 
and  purchasers  have  no  proper  interest."  ^^  The  Court  did  not 
specifically  indicate  whether  it  approved  the  assertion  of  the  lower 
court  that  the  failure  to  make  the  information  public  is,  in  and  of  itself, 
a  restraint  of  trade,  although  it  affirmed  that  part  of  the  decree  for- 
bidding the  dissemination  of  any  information  unless  it  was  made  public 
to  the  purchasing  and  distributing  trade. 

The  exception  formulated  by  the  Supreme  Court  in  favor  of  confi- 
dential communications  opens  the  door  to  evasion  and  subterfuge. 
There  is  no  reason  why  the  same  statistics  of  price,  production, 
shipments,  inventories,  etc.,  which  are  distributed  to  sellers  should 
not  be  made  available  to  buyers.  There  may  be  some  information 
which  cannot  be  widely  disseminated,  such  as  credit  information,  the 
circulation  of  which  under  the  laws  of  libel  is  privileged  only  if  limited. 
However,  while  such  information  may  properly  be  withheld  from  gen- 
eral circulation,  it  should  always  be  available  to  inspection  by  a  proper 
regulatory  agency  as  a  safeguard  against  its  improper  use,  as,  for 
example,  in  blacklisting  customers. 

Except  for  such  unusual  situations,  there  is  no  reason  why  all  infor- 
mation circulated  should  not  be  made  available  to  purchasers  and  the 
public.  Disparity  of  knowledge  may  produce  a  disparity  of  bargain- 
ing power.  The  effect  of  publicity  is  to  promote  fair  competition  and 
safeguard  the  program  against  abuse.  The  validity  of  statistical 
programs  should  be  expressly  conditioned,  in  any  statutory  revision,  on 
the  full  disclosure  to  purchasers  and  the  public  of  all  information 
distributed  to  members,  with  narrow  exceptions  covering  certain 
kinds  of  information  which  may  properly  be  withheld  from  general 
circulation.  This  would  have  the  effect  of  making  unlawful  any 
program,  no  matter  what  its  form  or  scope,  in  which  information  is 
not  made  available  to  purchasers  and  the  public.  Despite  such 
publicity,  however,  statistical  programs  may  be  illegal  or  presump- 
tively unlawful  for  other  reasons  set  forth  below. 

(2)  Closed  and  past  transactions. — In  Maple  Flooring  Mfrs.  Assn. 
V.  United  States  ^^  the  Court  upheld  a  plan  involving  the  reporting  of 
detailed  information  in  past  and  closed  transactions  and  the  circula- 
tion of  abstract  statistical  summaries  that  did  not  disclose  the  details 
of  individual  transactions  or  identify  the  policies  of  members.  The 
reporting   and   distribution   of  information   concerning  past  prices, 

'8  (1925)  268  U.  S.  588. 

"  (193fi)  297  U.  S.  553,  597,  604. 

60  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  1934)  15  F.  Supp.  817,  899. 

6"  (1936)  297  U.  S.  553,  604. 

"  (1925)  268  U.  S.  563. 


22  CONOENTRATlOiN  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

and  other  data  dealing  with  closed  transactions,  contribute  materially 
to  a  knowledge  of  market  conditions,  to  better  business  judgments 
and  to  a  better  adjustment  of  supply  to  market  demand.  There 
can  be  no  objection  to  a  program  of  reporting  and  disseminating 
information  dealing  with  past  activities  that  is  given  wide  publicity 
unless  the  system  is  perverted  and  used  as  a  cloak  for  a  price-fixing 
agreement.  The  danger  of  such  abuse  is  so  slight  in  comparison  with 
the  economic  advantages  of  widespread  and  accurate  knowledge  of 
market  conditions  that  the  rule  of  the  Maple  Flooring  ^^  case  regarding 
past  reporting  should  not  be  touched  in  any  legislative  revision  of 
the  antitrust  laws. 

(3)  Filing  of  current  and  future  prices. — Prior  to  the  decision  in 
Sugar  Institute,  Inc.,  v.  United  States, ^^  it  was  generally  believed  that 
any  program  involving  the  filing  and  dissemination  of  current  and 
future  prices  violated  the  Sherman  law.^^  In  the  Sugar  Institute^^ 
case,  the  Supreme  Court  modified  the  decree  of  the  lower  court,  which 
forbade  the  dissemination  of  current  and  future  price  statistics. 
The  collection  and  distribution  of  such  statistics  were  sanctioned  by 
the  Court  because  it  had  been  the  historic  practice  in  the  sugar 
industry  for  the  announcement  of  any  advance  in  price  to  be  widely 
circulated,  but  the  Court  was  careful  to  make  explicit  its  prohibition 
against  any  requirement  that  there  be  adherence  to  these  prices  by 
members  of  the  industry.  The  Court  was  careful  to  limit  its  decision  in 
this  regard  to  the  facts  of  the  case  before  it.  Nevertheless,  some 
commentators  have  interpreted  the  decision  as  laying  down  a  rule  of 
general  application,  which  would  permit  the  interchange  of  current 
and  future  price  information  in  all  industries  regardless  of  the  prior 
trade  practice.^^  Although  it  is  reasonably  clear  that  the  Court  did 
not  intend  to  lay  down  any  rule  of  general  application,  it  must  be 
admitted  that  its  decision  is  somewhat  ambiguous.  In  view  of  this 
uncertainty,  the  question  of  the  extent  to  which  current  and  future 
price-reporting  should  be  permitted  must  be  faced  in  any  program  of 
statutory  revision.  If  the  prices  of  each  seller  are  disclosed  in 
identifiable  form,  future  price-reporting  can  easily  become  a  device 
by  which  price  leadership  is  facilitated.  Concealed  price  arrange- 
ments, which  are  incapable  of  detection,  are  thus  fostered. 

Even  if  the  disclosures  of  individual  prices  were  forbidden,  the 
propriety  of  permitting  the  collection  and  dissemination  of  current 
and  future  prices  under  any  circumstances  would  still  have  to  be 
determined.  It  cannot  be  said  that  such  reporting,  in  and  of  itself, 
will  eliminate  price  competition  under  all  circumstances.  It  is  con- 
ceivable that  a  properly  formulated  and  carefully  administered  plan 
in  highly  competitive  industries  might  make  competition  more  intelli- 
gent and  effective  and  less  wasteful.  On  the  other  hand,  it  is  unde- 
niable that  the  practice  may  induce  the  making  of  concealed  price 
arrangements  and  thus  be  used  for  improper  purposes. 

«3  Ihid.  For  recent  consent  decrees  permitting  the  disclosure  of  closed  and  past  transactions  see  United 
States  V.  Natimal  Containers  Assn.,  C.  C.  H.  Trade  Reg.  Serv.  (8th  ed.),  par.  25,434  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  1940); 
United  States  v.  Long  Island  Sand  &  Gravel  Producers'  Assn.,  id.  par.  25,475  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  J940). 

«<  (1930)  297  U.  S.  553. 

"  See  United  States  v.  American  Linseed  Oil  Co.  (1923)  262  U.  S.  371. 

M  (193r.)  297  U.  S.  553. 

"  Donovan,  The  ElTect  of  the  Decision  in  the  Sugar  Institute  Case  upon  Trade  Association  Activities 
(1936)  84  U.  of  Pa.  L.  Rev.  929;  see  Kirsh,  Trade  Associations  in  Law  and  Business  (1938)  63  et  seq.  For  a 
recent  consent  decree  forbidding  the  dissemination  of  current  and  future  price  statistics  see  United  States  v. 
Southern  California  Marble  Assn.,  C.  C.  H.  Trade  Reg.  Serv.  (8th  ed.)  par.  25,607  (S.  D.  Calif.  1940). 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  23 

It  would  bo  unwise,  therefore,  to  sanction  current  and  future  price 
reporting  as  a  legitimate  trade  association  activity  under  all  condi- 
tions. Absolute  prohibition  could  only  be  justified  by  reason  of  the 
close  proximity  of  the  practice  to  direct  price-fixing  and  the  likelihood 
of  abuse.  An  intermediate  position  is  possible.  The  practice  may  be 
made  presumptively  unlawful,  the  burden  being  shifted  to  those 
engaged  in  the  practice  to  establish  that  it  has  not  been  employed  to 
accomplish  ends  forbidden  by  the  statute  and  that  its  operation  has 
not  resulted  in  the  elimination  or  impairment  of  competition.  The 
practice  is  to  be  presumptively  unlawful  notwithstanding  the  full 
publicity  accorded  the  information.  In  the  absence  of  such  publicity, 
the  dissemination  of  current  and  future  price  data  should  be  absolutely 
unlawful. 

(4)  Agreement  to  adhere  to  filed  prices  Jor  a  fixed  period  of  time  or  not 
to  deviate  therefrom  without  prior  notice. — In  the  Sugar  Institute  ^^  case, 
the  Court  went  further  in  condemning  the  agreement  to  adhere  to  and 
not  to  deviate  from  filed  prices,  and  in  indicating  that  this  phase  of 
the  program  was  in  itself  unlawful,  than  it  has  with  regard  to  any 
other  feature.  It  can  therefore  be  stated  categorically  that  current 
or  future  price  reporting  coupled  with  such  an  agreement  is  unlawful.^* 

The  agreement  to  adhere  to  the  filed  price  or  other  conditions  of 
sale  for  a  fixed  period  of  time  or  not  to  deviate  therefrom  without 
prior  notice  apprises  competitors,  assuming  a  complete  disclosure  to 
them,  of  the  exact  terms  on  which  the  sales  by  their  rivals  will  be  made. 
It  facilitates  price  leadership  and  concealed  price  understandings. 
Even  without  such  disclosure,  it  introduces  rigidities  into  the  price 
structure  which  is  thereby  made  less  sensitive  and  responsive  to 
economic  change.  The  higgling  between  buyer  and  seller,  which 
tends  in  part  to  determine  prices  in  a  competitive  regime,  is  obviously 
circumscribed  so  long  as  the  seller  is  required  to  adhere  to  his  prices 
or  to  notify  the  combine  of  which  he  is  a  member,  of  any  proposed 
change  before  it  can  become  effective.  Such  requirements  inevitably 
impair  the  freedom  of  action  of  the  individual  tradesman  and  enable 
him  to  resist  the  efforts  of  buyers  to  obtain  better  terms.  Such 
agreements  are  manifestly  inconsistent  with  the  maintenance  of  com- 
petition, and  the  rule  of  the  Sugar  Institute  case  ""^  in  this  should  not 
be  disturbed  in  any  statutory  revision. 

(5)  Waiting  period. — An  agreement  to  wait  for  a  period  of  time  after 
the  announcement  of  a  proposed  change  in  any  price,  term,  or  condi- 
tion of  sale  before  the  change  from  a  previously  announced  price, 
term,  or  condition  can  become  effective  is  subject  to  the  same  legal 
and  practical  objections  as  the  agreement  to  adhere.  It  prevents 
businessmen  from  giving  immediate  effect  to  their  judgment  of  current 
market  conditions  and  retards  the  adjustment  of  price  and  production 
to  demand.  It  also  encourages  sub  rosa  efforts  by  the  combination 
and  by  business  rivals  to  induce  the  withdrawal  of  a  proposed  reduc- 
tion of  price.  Wliere  there  is  a  waiting  period,  tendencies  toward 
coercive  price  maintenance  are  more  likely  to  be  effective  than  where 
a  producer  can  give  immediate  effect  to  a  price  change.  The  seller 
or  producer  should  retain  the  right  to  set  his  own  prices  and  to  change 

68  (1936)  297  U.  S.  553. 

«» Id.  at  601;  United  States  v.  American  Linseed  Oil  Co.  0923).  262  U.  S.  371. 

'"  (1936)  297  U.  S.  553.  For  recent  consent  decrees  prohibiting  agreements  to  adhere  see  United  States  v. 
Southern  Calif.  Marble  Assn.,  C.  C.  H.  Trade  Reg.  Serv.  (8th  ed.)  par.  25,607  (S.  D.  Calif.  1940);  United 
States  V.  Underwood  Elliott  Fisher  Co.,  id.  par.  25,433  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  1940). 


24  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

prices,  terms,  or  conditions  of  sale  at  any  time  whatsoever  and  at  his 
own  discretion.     The  waiting  period  should  be  specifically  outlawed. 

(6)  Disclosure  oj  individual  price  and  production  data. — The  socially 
desirable  function  of  supplying  helpful  information  of  the  funda- 
mental conditions  affecting  an  industry  can  often  be  performed  with- 
out a  disclosure  of  the  policies  of  individual  businessmen  concerning 
prices,  production,  shipments,  inventories,  terms  and  conditions  of 
sale,  and  other  similar  matters.  Disclosure  of  the  specific  facts  of 
each  sale  does  not  necessarily  add  to  the  value  of  the  statistics,  and 
the  use  of  proper  cost-accounting  methods  and  the  proper  breakdown 
of  statistical  data  falling  short  of  complete  identification  is  usually 
sufficient  to  make  a  statistical  service  useful  in  the  eflacient  conduct 
of  a  business.     This  fact  has  received  judicial  recognition.^^ 

There  are  occasions,  however,  when  some  disclosure  of  individual 
policies  is  necessary  to  make  statistical  data  useful.  One  such  in- 
stance would  be  to  prevent  over-reaching  by  buyers  whose  purpose  it 
is  to  force  prices  down  by  misrepresenting  the  quotations  of  other 
sellers,  or  who  deal  unfairly  with  sellers  in  other  ways.  Disclosure 
of  individual  policies  on  such  occasions  has  been  held  to  be  lawful.'^ 
Over-reaching  by  buyers  may  result  in  one  buyer  receiving  a  lower 
price  as  contrasted  with  other  buyers,  or  a  disproportionate  share  of 
available  supplies  of  merchandise.  Both  results  are  socially  harmful. 
There  are  other  times  when  price  information  to  be  meaningful  must 
be  capable  of  identification,  as  where  the  products  of  an  industry  are 
unstandardized.  The  dangers  in  permitting  such  disclosures  must  be 
recognized.  Such  revelations  invite  coercion  and  reprisal,  are  con- 
ducive to  price  leadership,  price  uniformity  and  other  price  arrange- 
ments, and  may  in  the  case  of  production  data  lead  to  a  restriction 
of  output. 

There  are  some  intimations  in  the  cases  that  the  identification  of 
information  concerning  prices,  terms,  and  conditions  of  sale  is  generally 
improper,  but  there  are  no  such  intimations  with  respect  to  the  iden- 
tification of  information  concerning  production,  inventories,  etc. 
While  the  revelation  of  individual  policies  concerning  such  matters 
as  plant  capacity  may  not  be  fraught  with  danger,  the  same  cannot 
always  be  said  for  full  disclosures  concerning  the  volume  or  cost  of 
production,  shipments,  inventories,  and  similar  matters. 

It  is  our  conclusion  that  decisions  do  not  adequately  protect  against 
the  evasion  of  the  statutory  purposes  by  the  improper  use  of  identifi- 
able data.  With  regard  to  information  concerning  prices  and  current 
production,  it  would  appear  that  legislative  correction  through  the 
creation  of  a  statutory  presumption  of  illegality  would  be  preferable 
to  an  unqualified  prohibition  since,  as  stated,  some  disclosures  may  be 
socially  desirable.  Whether  a  similar  presumption  should  be  invoked 
on  the  occasion  of  the  disclosure  of  other  data  in  identifiable  form,  is 
a  question  that  should  be  left  open  until  our  knowledge  of  the  effects 
of  such  disclosures  is  enlarged. 

Here  again,  whatever  information  is  permitted  to  be  disclosed  to 
the  members  of  the  association  must  be  accessible  to  purchasers  and 
the  public,  with  appropriate  exceptions  to  cover  information  which 
is  incapable  of  wide  circulation.     Any  information  that  is  not  pub- 

"  See  United  States  v.  American  Linseed  Oil  Co.  (1923),  262  U.  S.  371,  389,  390;  Maple  Flooring  Mfrs.  Assn. 
y.  United  States  (.192^),  2G8V.S.  563,  57^,  5S2. 
»  Cement  Mfrs.  Protective  Assn.  v.  United  States  (1925),  2fi8  U.  S.  588. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  25 

lished  should  be  open  to  the  inspection  of  an  appropriate  governmental 

agency. 

(7)  Interpretative  comments. — Although  the  Court  has  frowned  upon 
the  circulation  of  interpretative  comments,  advice,  or  suggestions  by 
trade  associations  concerning  the  data  disseminated  by  them,  it  has 
not  held  that  such  comments  are  per  se  illegal."  The  skilled  interpre- 
tation of  the  published  reports  may  clearly  indicate  to  the  members 
that  "harmony  of  action"  is  "likely  to  prove  profitable  in  proportion 
as  it  is  unitedly  pursued."  '^  Interpretative  comments  thus  may 
induce  uniformity  of  price  and  the  arbitrary  curtailment  of  production. 
Price  rigidity  is  undesirable  whether  the  result  of  agreement  or  the 
"voluntary"  response  to  a  "pregnant"  suggestion.  Devices  which 
engender  a  pernicious  result,  whether  they  consist  of  an  agreement  or 
something  that  falls  short  of  an  agreement,  should  bo  prevented  so  far 
as  is  practicable.  As  regards  interpretative  comments,  a  choice 
must  be  made  between  an  outright  legislative  prohibition  and  the 
creation  of  a  statutory  presumption.  Although  interpretative  com- 
ments have  been  employed  in  the  past  as  a  means  of  evading  the 
statute,  a  complete  prohibition  would  outlaw  the  circulation  of  com- 
ments which  conceivably  might  be  socially  desirable.  The  wiser 
choice,  therefore,  would  appear  to  be  to  formulate  a  statutory  pre- 
sumption, imposing  a  heavy  burden  on  those  employing  the  device  to 
show  that  its  use  is  consistent  with  the  precepts  of  a  competitive 
order,  and  requiring  all  such  comments  to  be  accessible  to  the  public. 

(8)  Meetings  and  discussions. — While  the  cases  do  not  condemn 
meetings  of  competitors  to  discuss  general  trade  conditions  or  topics 
of  mutual  interest,  they  do  indicate  that  meetings  at  which  prices, 
prospects  of  the  market,  production,  or  terms  and  conditions  of  sale 
are  discussed  may  be  outside  the  pale  of  legality. ^^  To  permit  dis- 
cussion of  prices,  for  example,  clears  the  path  for  implied  under- 
standings, gentlemen's  agreements,  or  unlawful  concerted  action  of 
some  form,  even  in  the  absence  of  a  definite  contract.  The  full  dis- 
closure of  prices  and  other  terms  of  sale  leads  to  the  imposition  of 
pressure  upon  price  laggards.  It  both  facilitates  the  maldng  of 
hidden  understandings  and  aids  in  their  enforcement  once  made.  It 
is  well  known  that  many  associations  have  paper  plans  of  undoubted 
validity,  but  seek  to  evade  the  prohibitions  of  the  law  by  discussions 
at  meetings  or  otherwise.  One  of  the  ways  to  strengthen  the  statute 
is  to  require  full  stenographic  records  of  all  meetings,  which  should 
always  be  available  for  examination  by  an  appropriate  regulatory 
agency,  and  to  make  taboo  the  discussion  of  certain  topics  which  are 
apt  to  result  in  some  form  of  collusive  restraint. 

(9)  Recommendations,  persuasion,  or  pressure  concerning  price  or 
production  policies. — The  recommendation  to  or  persuasion  of  a  mem- 
ber of  an  association  to  pursue  a  suggested  program  concerning  prices 
or  production  is  closely  allied  to  the  circulation  of  interpretative 
comments  and  the  discussion  by  members  of  prices,  production,  or 

"  See  American  Column  &  Lumber  Co.  v.  United  States  (1921),  257  U.  S.  377,  407,  411. 

M/d.  at411. 

"  See  American  Column  &  Lumber  Co.  v.  United  States  (1921),  2,57  U.  S.  377,  399,  405,  407;  United  States  v. 
American  Linseed  Oil  Co.  (1923),  2(52  U.  S.  371,  389;  Maple  Flooring  Mfrs.  Assn.  v.  United  States  (1925),  268 
U.  S.  563,  574,  586;  Cement  Mfrs.  Protective  Assn.  v.  United  States  (1925),  208  U.  S.  588,  601.  For  recent  con- 
sent decrees  prohibiting  the  discu.ssion  of  data  at  association  meetings  relating  to  production  or  conditions 
of  sale  see  United  States  v.  National  Containers  Assn.,  C.  C.  H.  Trade  Reg.  Serv.  (8th  ed.)  par.  25,434  (S.  D. 
N.  Y.  1940);  United  States  v.  Southern  Calif.  Marble  Assn.,  id.  par.  25,607  (S.  D.  Cahf.  1940). 

291144— 41— No.  88 3 


2Q  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

terms  and  conditions  of  sale.  Unlike  the  interpretative  comment, 
which  merely  purports  to  explain  the  meaning  of  the  accompanying 
data,  recommendations,  persuasion,  and  pressure  urge  or  compel  the 
adoption  of  a  stated  course  of  action.  The  pressure  to  observe  or 
maintain  the  suggested  program  is  usually  applied  through  an  active 
official  of  the  association  who  polices  the  industry,  investigates  the 
manner  in  which  members  conduct  their  business,  makes  recommenda- 
tions to  price  laggards  and  in  other  ways  exhorts  them  to  conform  their 
policies  with  those  of  the  other  members  of  the  association.  Although 
no  decision  specifically  holds  that  the  practice  in  and  of  itself  is  either 
lawful  or  unlawful,  it  may  be  a  significant  fact  from  which  an  agreement 
to  fix  prices  or  limit  production  may  be  inferred.'^  The  practice, 
which  is  inconsistent  with  the  maintenance  of  competition,  should  be 
expressly  prohibited  in  any  statutory  codification. 

(10)  Penalties. — Penalties  for  violation  of  the  provisions  of  an 
association  argument  were  imposed  in  one  of  the  plans  condemned  by 
the  Supreme  Court  ^^  and  were  absent  in  all  of  the  plans  that  have 
received  judicial  approval.'*  It  is  nevertheless  highly  questionable 
whether  the  mere  implementation  of  a  plan,  otherwise  valid,  with 
penalties,  will  vitiate  its  legality.  When  used  to  compel  adherence  to 
filed  prices  or  for  other  improper  purposes,  their  use  accentuates  the 
illegality  of  the  arrangement.  Placing  the  power  to  impose  penalties 
in  private  hands  is  an  extremely  dangerous  practice.  It  may,  however, 
be  desirable  to  assist  an  association  in  its  eft'orts  to  stamp  out  dishonest 
or  fraudulent  activities  and  raise  the  level  of  trade  practice  by  per- 
mitting it  to  impose  penalties  under  narrowly  restricted  circumstances 
provided  suitable  safeguards  to  prevent  abuse  are  provided. 

(11)  Miscellaneous  factors  that  may  affect  the  legality  of  statistical 
programs — (a)  Competitive  texture  of  the  industry. — There  is  a  distinc- 
tion between  the  role  of  business  information  in  industries  where  there 
are  few  sellers  and  its  function  under  conditions  of  more  active  com- 
petition. Where  an  industry  is  monopolistic,  the  dissemination  of 
information  may  tend  to  reduce  the  little  competition  that  might 
otherwise  prevail  and  may  facilitate  tacit  arrangements  of  a  restrictive 
nature. 

(b)  Demoralized  state  of  the  industry. — One  of  the  factors  considered 
by  the  Court  in  the  Sugar  Institute  case  ''^  in  determining  the  validity  of 
the  program  there  in  issue  was  the  depressed  condition  of  the  sugar 
industry  when  the  program  took  effect.  The  earlier  case  of  Appala- 
chian Coals,  Inc.,  v.  United  States, ^'^  also  indicated  that  industrial 
programs  designed  to  rehabilitate  a  demoralized  mdustry  and  to 
eliminate  unfair  trade  practices  might  be  accorded  greater  latitude 
than  similar  programs  operating  in  a  healthy  industry.  Although  the 
state  of  the  industry  should  be  a  factor  to  be  considered  with  all  the 
other  circumstances  in  determining  the  legality  of  a  plan,  there  should 
be  no  blanket  exemption  on  this  basis  without  strict  administrative 
supervision  by  a  governmental  agency. 

"  Sc6  American  Column  &  Lumber  Co.  v.  United  States  (1921),  257  U.  S.  377,  402.  For  a  recent  consent  de- 
croo  proliibitinc  the  use  of  pressure  or  persuasion  concerning  price  or  production  policies  see  United  States 
V.  Southern  Calif.  Marble  Assn.,  C.  C.  11.  Trade  Reg.  Scrv.  (8th  ed.)  par.  25,607  (S.  D.  Calif.  19-10). 

"  United  Stales  v.  American  Linseed  Oil  Co.  (1923),  262  IT.  S.  371.  For  a  recent  consent  decree  prohibiting 
the  imposition  of  a  penalty  on  a  member  of  a  trade  association  see  United  States  v.  Tile  Contractors'  Assn. 
of  America,  C.  O.  11.  Trade  Ueg.  Serv.  (Sth  e<l.')  par.  25,469  (N.  D.  111.  1940). 

'8  Maple  Flooring  Mfrs.  Assv.  v.  United  States  (1925),  268  U.  S.  563;  Cement  Mfrs.  Protective  Assn.  v.  United 
State.''  (1925),  268  U.  S.  588;  see  Sugar  Institute,  Inc.,  v.  United  States  (1936),  297  U.  S.  553. 

'« (1936)  297  U.  S.  653. 

8«  (1933)  288  U.  S.  344. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  27 

(c)  Ejject  on  prices. — Although  the  actual  effect  of  a  statistical 
program  upon  prices  is  evidentiary  of  its  compatibility  with  com- 
petition, it  is  not  conclusive  as  to  whether  it  may  in  the  future  result 
in  the  elimination  of  competition.  If  the  program  gri^atly  facilitates 
the  making  of  unlawful  price  arrangements,  it  siiould  not  be  given 
approval  merely  because  it  has  not  yet  all'ected  prices  adversely. 

{d)  Regulatory  agency. — In  all  the  decided  cases,  information  was 
collected  and  disseminated  by  unsupervised  trade  associations  or 
agencies  subject  to  the  control  of  the  association  in  question.  The 
lack  of  supervision  opens  the  door  to  the  improper  use  of  the  infor- 
mation by  the  association  and  to  favoritism.  These  dangers  may'  be 
avoided  in  various  wa3''s.  First,  trade  associations  might  be  subjected 
to  governmental  registration  and  supervision  with  suitable  standards, 
imposed  to  govern  the  conduct  of  their  statistical  activities.  Second,, 
a  governmental  agency  might  collect  and  disseminate  all  statistical; 
data.  The  collection  and  dissemination  by  a  governmental  agency 
of  the  vast  amount  of  statistical  information  now  distributed  by 
individual  trade  associations  would  in  all  probability  impose  a  burden 
which  no  governmental  body  should  be  expected  to  carry.  Third, 
the  collection  and  dissemination  might  be  done  by  private,  impartial 
agencies  independent  of  the  associations  and  licensed  by  tlie  Federal 
Government.  This  was  suggested  by  the  N.  R.  A.^'  This  would  be 
desirable  in  the  absence  of  any  regulation  of  the  associations;  if 
associations  are  required  to  be  registered,  it  might  be  unnecessary  to 
set  up  any  separate  instrumentalities  for  this  purpose.  The  first 
alternative  is  considered  to  be  the  most  feasible. 

It  is  vital  that  the  mformation  which  is  collected  and  disseminated 
should  be  available  to  the  Government  to  satisfy  its  urgent  need  for 
comprehensive  and  adequate  statistics.  All  information  should  be 
filed  with  an  appropriate  governmental  department  or  agency,  and 
should  be  available  for  public  examination.  To  coordinate  industrial 
statistics  obtained  from  numerous  trades  and  industries  it  may  be 
necessary  to  obtain  special  reports  from  trade  associations.  It  is 
essential  therefore  that  the  department  or  agency  charged  with  such 
coordination  be  empowered  to  request  such  additional  reports  as 
may  be  necessary  and  advisable. 

(E)  SUGGESTIONS 

Because  the  different  features  that  may  be  included  in  any  program 
to  disseminate  trade  statistics  vary  in  their  effect  upon  the  price 
structure  and  in  the  extent  to  which  they  may  be  used  to  cloak  unlaw- 
ful arrangements  concernmg  prices,  it  is  unwise  to  treat  th(^m  all  in 
the  same  manner,  or  even  to  divide  them  categorically  into  the  lawful 
and  the  unlawful.  Some  features,  in  and  of  themselves,  so  closely 
approximate  price-fixing  or  agreements  concerning  production  or 
may  be  so  easily  perverted  to  accomplish  these  purposes,  that  they 
should  be  unqualifiedly  prohibited  in  any  statutory  revision. 

Other  features,  while  potentially  harmful,  since  they  may,  under 
some  circumstances,  result  in  imderstandings  concerning  prices, 
production,  or  terms  and  conditions  of  sale,  may  perform  socially 
desirable  functions  if  they  are  not  abused.     They  should  neither  be 

81  N.  R.  A.  Office  Memo.  228,  June  8, 1934;  see  Lyon  &  Abramson,  The  Economics  of  Open  Price  System  s 
(1936),  Uhetseq. 


28  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

unqualifiedly  prohibited  nor  unqualifiedly  permitted.  The  restric- 
tions on  these  features  shoidd  be  cast  in  terms  of  a  rebuttable  presump- 
tion of  illegality.  The  eftect  of  such  a  presumption  will  be  to  discour- 
age the  adoption  of  programs  which  include  these  features,  to  restrict 
them  to  socially  useful  channels  when  adopted,  and  to  facilitate  the 
enforcement  of  the  statute  by  the  Government,  since  the  burden  of 
justification  will  rest  upon  those  engaging  in  the  activities. 

As  regards  still  other  features  of  programs  for  disseminating  statis- 
tical mformation,  their  susceptibility  to  abuse  is  so  slight  when  com- 
pared with  the  social  advantages  to  be  derived  from  then  use,  that 
they  should  be  unqualifiedly  permitted.  By  so  doing,  much  uncer- 
tainty will  be  lifted  from  this  branch  of  the  law. 

It  is  not  enough  to  divide  the  features  of  statistical  programs  into 
these  three  categories.  Full  consideration  must  be  given  to  the 
potency  of  publicity  in  the  correction  of  the  evils  arising  out  of  the 
collection  and  dissemination  of  statistics.  There  should  be  a  definite 
requirement  of  publicity  as  a  condition  to  the  legality  of  any  statistical 
program.  Despite  publicity,  some  features  should  still  be  presump- 
tively unlawful  and  some  unqualifiedly  unlawful. 

Trade  associations  have  a  distinct  service  to  perform  in  modern 
industrial  society.  Many,  indeed  most,  of  the  activities  in  which  they 
engage  are  perfectly  consistent  with  the  maintenance  of  price  compe- 
tition and  go  a  long  way  in  raising  the  standards  of  competitive  rela- 
tions. Regulation  of  unfair  and  deceptive  competitive  practices,  the 
arbitration  of  commercial  disputes,  the  standardization  of  identity  and 
quality  of  products,  the  improvement  of  conditions  of  labor,  the  regis- 
tration of  trade-marks  and  original  styles  and  designs,  the  conserva  tion 
of  natural  resources,  the  elimination  of  wasteful  practices,  and  the  pro- 
motion of  efficiencies  in  production  and  distribution  are  only  a  few 
of  the  fields  in  which  trade  associations  perform  a  distinct  social 
service. 

The  criticisms  of  the  trade  associations'  activities  considered  in  this 
section  are  not  to  be  taken  as  condemnations  of  the  trade  association 
movement  as  such,  nor  are  the  suggestions  that  have  been  made  for 
legislative  correction  intended  to  limit  the  capacity  of  trade  associa- 
tions to  render  a  real  public  service  to  industry  and  the  community. 

(F)    CONCLUSIONS 

A,  Whether  or  not  full  publicity  is  accorded  any  statistical  program 
and  whether  or  not  the  information  is  filed  with  a  governmental 
department  or  agency,  the  following  features  of  such  programs  should 
be  unqualifiedly  prohibited: 

(1)  Any  agreement  to  adhere  for  any  period  of  time  to  any  price, 

term,  or  condition  of  sale  previously  fixed,  announced,  or 
filed; 

(2)  Any  agreement  not  to  make  any  change  in  any  price,  term, 

or  condition  of  sale  without  giving  prior  notice  of  such 
change ; 

(3)  Any  agreement  to  observe  a  waiting  period  before  an  an- 

nounced change  from  a  previously  fixed,  announced,  or 
filed  price  can  become  effective; 
(11  All  discussions  by  competitors  which  result  or  are  likely  to 
result  in  uniformity  ot  action  concerning  price  or  production 
policies ; 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  29 

(5)  All  recommendations  to,  persuasion  of,  or  pressure  upon,  any 
member  to  follow,  observe,  or  maintain  any  suggested 
program  concerning  prices  or  production. 

B.  Whether  or  not  full  publicity  is  accorded  any  statistical  program 
and  whether  or  not  the  information  is  filed  with  a  governmental 
department  or  agency,  the  following  features  of  such  programs  should 
be  presumptively  unlawful: 

(1)  The  filing  and  communication,  collection,  or  dissemination  of 

any  information  concerning  current  or  future  prices,  terms, 
or  conditions  of  sale; 

(2)  The  disclosure  to  competitors  of  any  information  concerning 

the  prices  or  volume  of  production  of  individual  members 
of  the  association; 

(3)  The  communication  or  circulation  of  interpretative  comments 

which  result  or  are  likely  to  result  in  uniformity  of  action  in 
respect  of  prices  or  production. 

C.  The  following  type  of  statistical  program  should  be  permitted: 
The  communication,  collection,  and  dissemination  of  information 

concerning  prices,  terms,  and  conditions  of  sale  and  production  policies 
that  relate  to  closed  and  past  transactions,  subject,  however,  to  the 
following  conditions: 

(a)  There  must  be  no  disclosure  of  individual  price  and  produc- 

tion policies,  except  when  necessary  to  prevent  over- 
reaching by  buyers ; 

(b)  The  information  concerning  prices,  production,  inventories, 

etc.,  must  be  disclosed  to  anyone  on  request  and  filed  with 
a  governmental  department  or  agencj^; 

(c)  The  information  must  be  complete,  accurate,  and  truthful; 

(d)  The  information  must  be  collected  and  disseminated  by  a 

registered  association  in  accordance  with  the  rules  and 
regulations  prescribed  by  an  appropriate  regulatory 
agency. 

DEGREE  OF  MARKET  CONTROL 

(A)    DEFINITION    OF    TERMS 

As  most  associations  embrace  a  majority  of  the  persons  in  their 
mdustries,  it  is  not  generally  appreciated  that  arrangements  elim- 
inating competition  are  frequently  made  by  minority  groups  lack- 
ing control  of  the  market  in  which  they  operate.  Although  unable 
completely  to  suppress  competition  in  their  markets,  the  activities  of 
such  groups  do  affect  general  competitive  conditions  and  may  place 
their  members  in  position  of  advantage  in  their  relations  with 
competitors  or  purchasers. 

Any  distinction  between  minority  and  majority  groups  involves 
numerous  definitional  difficulties.  To  determine  the  degree  of  market 
control  of  any  group,  it  is  necessary  to  define  the  industry  of  which  the 
group  is  a  part  and  the  market  m  which  it  docs  business.  In  the 
window-glass  industry,  for  example,  handblown  competes  with 
machine-made  glass.  A  combination  of  "manufacturers  of  handblown 
glass  may  be  deemed  a  monopolistic  group  if  handblown  glass  is 


3Q  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

regarded  as  a  separate  industry,  while  in  relation  to  the  entire 
window-glass  industry,  it  may  be  but  a  minor  factor.  On  a  nationwide 
basis,  a  group  may  be  almost  infinitesimal,  while  in  the  areas  in  which 
its  products  are  sold,  it  may  enjoy  a  position  of  dominance. 

Nor  is  it  easy,  once  the  preliminary  difficulties  in  defining  the  indus- 
try and  market  are  overcome,  to  determine  the  point  at  which  the 
degree  of  control  can  be  said  to  be  monopolistic.  It  seems  reasonably 
clear  that  monopoly  is  something  less  than  complete  domination,  but 
how  much  less  the  decisions  do  not  reveal  with  any  clarity.  For 
present  purposes,  the  distinction  lies  in  the  ability  to  set  the  market 
price.  A  group  sufficiently  powerful  to  dictate  the  market  price  is 
monopolistic;  a  combination  lacking  such  power  is  denominated  a 
minority  group. 

(B)    SUMMARY    OF    AUTHORITIES 

In  the  early  decisions,  the  degree  of  market  control  was  not  deemed 
a  material  factor  in  determining  the  legality  of  an  arrangement 
restrictive  of  competition.^-  The  classic  enunciation  of  this  view  is  to 
be  found  in  the  monumental  opinion  of  Judge  Taft  in  Addyston  Pi/pe  & 
Steel  Co.  Y.  United  States. ^^  Although  the  defendants  in  the  Addyston 
case  claimed  that  their  output  did  not  exceed  30  percent  of  the  na- 
tional production  of  cast-iron  pipe,  their  power  in  the  markets  in 
which  they  disposed  of  their  products  was  extensive.  Nevertheless, 
Judge  Taft,  for  the  purposes  of  decision,  treated  the  combine  as  a 
nonmonopolistic  group  and  specifically  held  that  price-fixing  is  unlaw- 
ful whether  practiced  by  majority  or  minority  groups. 

Upon  this  review  of  the  law  and  the  authorities,  we  can  have  no  doubt  that 
the  association  of  the  defendants,  however  reasonable  the  prices  they  fixed,  how- 
ever great  the  competition  they  had  to  encounter,  and  however  great  the  necessity 
for  curbing  themselves  by  joint  agreement  from  committing  financial  suicide  by 
ill-advised  competition,  was  void  at  common  law,  because  in  restraint  of  trade, 
and  tending  to  a  monopoly.  *  *  *  Now,  the  restraint  [the  defendants]  thus 
imposed  on  themselves  was  only  partial.  It  did  not  cover  the  United  States. 
There  was  not  a  complete  monopoly.  It  was  tempered  by  the  fear  of  competition, 
and  it  affected  only  a  part  of  the  price.  But  this  certainly  does  not  take  the 
contract  of  association  out  of  the  annulling  effect  of  the  rule  against  monopolies.®* 

In  Chesapeake  cfc  Ohio  Fuel  Co.  v.  United  States  ^^  the  court  held 
illegal  an  exclusive  sales  agency  which  had  been  formed  to  market 
about  30  percent  of  the  coal  and  about  45  percent  of  the  coke  which 
was  produced  in  the  Kanawha  district  of  West  Virginia.  The  coal 
of  the  combine  was  less  than  1  percent  of  that  sold  in  the  same 
markets  in  which  it  competed  and  the  coke  sold  met  "severe"  com- 
petition in  all  markets.  The  sales  agency  was  given  the  power  to  fix 
the  prices  and  to  control  the  production  of  the  members  of  the  groups. 
Although  the  combination  was  subject  to  effective  competition  in  all 
markets,  it  was  held  illegal  since  it  deprived  the  public  of  the  benefits 
of  competition  within  the  group.  "The  law  reaches  combinations 
which  may  fall  short  of  complete  control  of  a  trade  or  business,  and 
does  not  await  the  consolidation  of  many  small  combinations  into  the 
huge  'trust'  which  shall  control  the  production  and  sale  of  a 
commodity."  ^^ 

«2  Addyston  Pipe  and  Steel  Co.  v.  United  States  (C.  C.  A.  6th,  1898)  85  Fed.  271,  aff'd  (1899),  175  U.  S.  211; 
Chesapeolct  and  Ohio  Fuel  Co.  v.  Unit((l  Stairs  (C.  C.  A.  6th,  1902),  115  Fed.  610. 
M  (C.  C.  A.  6th,  1898)  85  Fed.  271,  a/fd  (isy.))  175  U.  S.  211. 
e<  (C.  C.  A.  6th,  1898)  85  Fed.  271,  alT'd  (1899)  175  U.  S.  211. 
8»  (C.  C.  A.  6th,  1902)  115  Fed.  610. 
*6  Id.  at  624. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  31 

Thus  the  law  stood  until  the  decision  in  Standard  Oil  Co.  oj  New 
Jersey  v.  United  States,^''  in  which  Chief  Justice  White,  in  the  formula- 
tion of  the  rule  of  reason,  fused  the  dual  concepts  of  restraint  of  trade 
and  monopoly: 

The  ambiguity  [in  the  act],  if  any,  is  involved  in  determining  what  is  intended 
by  monopolize.  But  this  amljiguity  is  readily  dispelled  in  tlie  liglit  of  the  pre- 
vious history  of  the  law  of  restraint  of  trade  to  which  we  have  referred  and  the 
indication  which  it  gives  of  the  practical  evolution  by  which  monopoly  and  the 
acts  which  produce  the  same  results  as  monopoly,  that  is,  an  undue  restraint  of 
the  course  of  trade,  all  came  to  be  spoken  of  as,  and  to  be  indeed  synonymous 
with,  restraint  of  trade. ^^ 

The  Com't's  discussion  is  rather  obscure  and  it  is  difficult  to  deter- 
mine whether  it  intended  to  differentiate  between  minority  and  major- 
ity groups,  holding  only  the  activities  of  the  latter  unlawful,  or  whether 
its  purpose  was  to  promulgate  a  rule  of  reason  applicable  to  all  the 
activities  of  both  minority  and  majority  combinations. 

Most  of  the  combinations  invalidated  both  before  and  after  1911 
possessed  monopoly  power.  Thus,  in  United  States  v.  Joint  Traffic 
Assn.^^  the  combination  embraced  "most  (but  not  all)"  of  the  carriers 
operatmg  between  Chicago  and  the  iitlantic  coast;  "a  very  large  part" 
of  the  hnseed  products  business  was  done  by  the  defendants  in  United 
States  V.  American  Linseed  Oil  Co.;'^'^  the  buyers  of  hvestock  who  agreed 
not  to  bid  against  each  other  and  to  fix  prices  in  Swift  &  Co.  v.  United 
States  ^^  controlled  about  60  percent  of  the  national  commerce  in  fresh 
meats.  But  in  American  Column  cfc  Lumber  Co.  v.  United  States  ^^  a 
combination  wliich  produced  only  one-third  of  the  total  national  out- 
put of  hardwood  was  condemned.  Although  its  control  in  particular 
markets  is  not  disclosed,  the  minority  opinion  assumes  that  the  com- 
bine was  subjected  to  effective  outside  competition.  Despite  this 
fact,  the  adverse  effect  upon  the  general  price  level  engendered  l^y  the 
defendants'  activities  indicates  that  the  combination  possessed  con- 
siderable power.  The  tenor  of  the  Com't's  opinion,  however,  espe- 
cially when  read  in  the  light  of  the  dissent,  is  that  production  and 
price  control  by  any  group  of  competitors,  no  matter  what  its  size,  is 
interdicted  by  the  Sherman  law. 

There  are  four  decisions  wiiich,  while  not  purporting  to  overturn  the 
clear-cut  rule  of  the  Addyston  case,^^  give  considerable  weigJit  to  the 
combine's  lack  of  monopoly  power.  In  Board  of  Trade  of  the  City  of 
Chicago  v.  United  States  ^*  a  restriction  of  an  organized  exchange  against 
grain  purchases  after  closing  hours  at  prices  in  excess  of  the  final  bid 
in  the  open  market  was  sustained.  The  exchange's  regulation  did  not 
eliminate  but  merely  regularized  competition  for  onlj'^  a  small  part  of 
the'working  day  in  a  situation  far  different  from  that  obtaining  in  the 
ordinary  industrial  market.  The  case  dealt  witli  a  special  situation 
and  the  tendency  of  the  Court  has  been  to  limit  it  to  its  facts.*^  The 
language  of  the  opinion,  however,  leans  toward  the  view  that  arrange- 
ments which  have  but  a  partial  and  not  a  controlling  effect  on  the 
market  price  may  be  permissible. 

8'  (1911)  221  U.  S.  1. 

88  Id.  at  61. 

89  (1898)  171  U.  S.  505. 
»o  (1923)  262  U.  S.  371. 
»i  (1906)  196  U.  S.  375. 
"  (1921)  257  U.  S.  377. 

M  (C.  C.  A.  6th,  1898)  85  Fed.  271,  aff'd  (1899),  175  U.  S.  211. 
«<  (1918)  246  U.  S.  231. 

»«  United  States  v.  Trenton  Potteries  Company  (1927),  273  U.  S.  392,  401;  United  States  v.  Socony-Vacuum 
Oil  Co.  (1940),  310  U.  S.  150,  217. 


32  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

In  National  Assn.  of  Window  Glass  Manufacturers  v.  United  States,^ 
the  Supreme  Court  validated  an  agreement  between  an  association 
of  all  the  manufacturers  of  handblown  window  glass  and  a  labor 
union  controlling  the  labor  supply  of  this  branch  of  the  window- 
glass  industry.  The  number  of  skilled  laborers  was  insufficient  to 
keep  all  plants  operating  at  full  capacity  during  the  entire  year.  The 
agreement  provided  that  the  manufacturers  were  to  be  divided  into 
two  groups,  each  to  have  a  full  labor  complement  for  a  part  of  the  year. 
This  was  deemed  preferable  to  each  working  at  partial  capacity  during 
the  entire  year.  Handblown  glass  competes  with  the  machine-made 
product  and  comprises  but  a  minor  part  of  the  total  national  output  of 
window  glass.  It  is  apparent  from  the  opinion  of  the  Court,  which  is 
quite  anibiguous,  that  some  weight  was  attached  to  the  small  propor- 
tion of  window  glass  produced  by  members  of  the  combination.  The 
Court  was  struck  by  the  fact  that  the  arrangement  was  an  effort  by  a 
rapidly  dying  industry  to  prevent  or  at  least  retard  its  extmction.  The 
case  dealt  with  a  unique  situation,  has  rarely  been  cited,  and  has  had 
little  generative  effect  as  a  precedent. 

That  the  Court  might  permit  a  minority  group  under  some  circum- 
stances to  eliminate  competition  among  its  members  is  more  strongly 
indicated  by  Standard  0%  Co.  {Indiana)  v.  United  States  ^  (Cracking 
case).  There  the  fixation  of  royalty  rates  as  part  of  a  cross-licensing 
arrangement  of  competing  patents  was  sustained  on  the  ground  that 
the  gasoline  produced  by  the  patented  cracking  process  competed  with 
gasoline  sold  by  unpatented  methods  and  that  the  proportion  of 
cracked  gas  sold  was  too  slight  to  have  any  effect  on  the  ultimate  price 
of  gasoline  to  consumers.  The  defendants  controlled  55  percent  of  the 
productive  capacity  of  cracked  gas,  and  the  Government  estimated 
that  they  were  responsible  for  81  percent  of  the  actual  production. 
Cracked  gas,  however,  constituted  about  26  percent  of  the  total  output 
of  gasoline.  The  Court  indicated  that  the  fixation  of  royalty  rates 
would  be  unlawful  if  the  position  and  capacity  of  defendants  efl^ectively 
enabled  them  to  dominate  the  industry,  but  that  they  could  agree  on 
the  price  or  royalty  to  be  charged  licensees  so  long  as  they  did  not 
control  the  market.  Thougli  the  implications  of  the  opinion  on  the 
question  under  consideration  are  quite  clear,  the  case  is  one  of  doubtful 
value  as  a  precedent  since  it  was  primarily  concerned  with  the  intri- 
cacies of  patent  pools  and  cross-licensing  agreements. 

In  Appalachian  Coals,  Inc.,  v.  United  States  ^  the  Court  upheld  an 
exclusive  sales  agency  formed  to  market  and  fix  the  price  of  54.21 
percent  of  the  coal  mined  in  the  Appalachian  area;  it  emphasized  the 
fact  that  the  defendants  were  subject  to  effective  outside  competition 
in  all  the  markets  in  which  their  product  was  sold  and  were  conse- 
quently unable  to  control  the  market  price  of  coal.  The  language  of 
the  Court,  when  contrasted  with  that  used  in  Chesapeake  c&  Ohio  Fuel 
Co.  V.  United  States,'^  illustrates  how  great  has  been  the  change  in 
attitude  toward  minority  combinations: 

The  mere  fact  that  the  parties  to  an  agreement  eliminate  competition  between 
themselves  is  not  enough  to  condemn  it.  *  *  *  The  more  serious  question 
relates  to  the  effect  of  the  plan  upon  competition  between  defendants  and  other 
producers.     *     *     *     While  conditions  are  more  favorable  to  the  position  of 

1  (1923)  263  U.  S.  403. 

2  (1931)  2S3  U.  S.  163. 

3  (1933)  288  U.  S.  344. 

*  (C.  C.  A.  6th,  1902)  115  Fed.  610. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  33 

defendants'  group  in  some  markets  than  in  others,  we  think  that  the  proof  clearly 
shows  that,  wherever  their  selling  agency  operates,  it  will  find  itself  confronted 
by  effective  competition  backed  by  virtually  inexhaustible  sources  of  supply, 
and  will  also  be  compelled  to  cope  witli  the  organized  buying  power  of  large 
consumers.  The  plan  cannot  be  said  either  to  contemplate  or  involve  the  fixing 
of  market  prices.^ 

While  the  case  gives  strong  support  to  the  legality  of  agreements 
eliminating  competition  among  the  members  of  a  minority  group,  it 
loses  some  value  as  a  precedent  by  the  fact  that  the  program  concerned 
itself  with  efforts  to  mitigate  the  hardships  of  producers  in  a  hope- 
lessly disorganized  and  depressed  mdustry  durmg  a  period  of  general 
depression  and  by  the  fact  that  it  was  submitted  to  the  court  before 
it  was  put  into  operation.  '  The  case,  moreover,  dealt  with  a  defensive 
combine  seeking  to  equalize  the  bargaining  power  between  weak 
sellers  pitted  against  mammoth  industrial  buyers.  Nevertheless,  the 
language  in  the  opinion  midoubtedly  favors  the  legality  of  minority 
combinations  whose  restraints  do  not  eliminate  competition  from  the 
market  itself. 

Two  further  factors  should  be  noted.  The  Court  in  the  Appalachian 
Coals  '^  case  indicated  that  the  test  of  legality  is  the  same  in  both 
merger  and  loose-laiit  combmation  cases.  The  element  of  market 
control  is  of  undoubted  importance  m  determining  the  legality  of 
mergers  and  consolidations  under  the  anti-trust  laws.^  But  the  de- 
cisions in  the  merger  field  cannot  be  reconciled  in  terms  of  percent- 
ages, and  the  merger  experience  teaches  how  unstable  a  criterion  is 
the  element  of  size  or  market  control.^  Secondly,  the  Court  ordered 
the  lower  court  to  retain  jurisdiction  of  the  cause,  so  as  to  enable 
the  Government  to  mstitute  further  proceedmgs  if  the  plan  in  opera- 
tion led  to  any  abuse.  The  retention  of  jurisdiction  in  itself  indicates 
that  no  rule  of  universal  application  in  respect  of  the  activities  of 
minority  groups  was  bemg  adopted. 

While  these  decisions  appear  to  support  the  view  that  agreements 
elimmating  competition  among  the  members  of  a  minority  group 
which  is  subject  to  effective  outside  competition  may  conceivably  be 
valid,  each  of  the  cases  is  limited  by  the  special  facts  and  circumstances 
already  noted. 

The  degree  of  market  control  as  a  factor  in  antitrust  litigation  has 
recently  been  reexamined  by  the  Supreme  Court.  Although  unnec- 
essary to  the  decision,  the  Cornet  in  the  Socony-Vacuum  case  ^ 
unequivocally  condemned  price-fixing  by  minority  groups  as  follows: 

The  group  making  those  agreements  may  or  may  not  have  power  to  control 
the  market.  But  the  fact  that  the  group  cannot  control  the  market  prices  does 
not  necessarily  mean  that  the  agreement  as  to  prices  has  no  utility  to  the  mem- 
bers of  the  combination.  The  effectiveness  of  price-fixing  agreements  is  de- 
pendent on  many  factors,  such  as  competitive  tactics,  position  in  the  industry, 
the  formula  underlying  price  policies.  Whatever  economic  justification  partic- 
ular price-fixing  agreements  may  be  thought  to  have,  the  law  does  not  permit 
an  inquiry  into  their  leasonableness.  They  are  all  banned  because  of  their 
actual  or  potential  threat  to  the  central  nervous  system  of  the  economy. 


»  Appalachian  Coals.  Inc.,  v.  United  States,  supra,  at  360,  361,  373. 

6  (1933)  288  U.  S.  344. 

'  Handler,  Industrial  Mergers  and  the  Anti-Trust  Laws  (1932),  32  Col.  L.  Rev.  179. 

8  Capital  combinations  controlling  50  percent  (United  States  v.  U.  S.  Steel  Corp.  (1920),  251  U.  S.  417), 
64  percent  ( United  States  v.  International  Harvester  Co.  (1927),  274  U.  S.  093),  and  even  90-95  percent  ( United 
States  V.  United  Shoe  Machinery  Co.  (1918),  247  U.  S.  32)  of  an  industry  have  been  sustained.  On  the  other 
hand,  integrations  covering  but  20  percent  (United  States  v.  Lehigh  Valley  Railroad  Co.  (1920),  254  U.  S. 
255),  and  33  percent  (United  States  v.  Reading  Co.  (1920),  253  U.  S.  26)  of  an  industry  have  been  declared 
illegal. 

» (1940)  310  U.  S.  150. 


34  CONCENTEATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Only  a  confusion  between  the  nature  of  the  offenses  under  those  two  sections 
*  *  *  would  lead  to  the  conclusion  that  power  to  fix  prices  was  necessary  for 
proof  of  a  price-fixing  conspiracy  under  §  1.'° 

The  Court  does  not  assert  that  the  absence  of  monopoly  power 
may  not  be  a  factor  in  determining  the  legality  of  other  activities  of 
trade  groups.  Its  discussion  relates  to  price-fixing  only.  However, 
its  analysis  appears  to  be  hostile  to  any  practices  which  suppress 
competition,  whether  indulged  by  minority  or  monopoly  groups. 

In  its  decision  in  the  Apex  Hosiery  case,  ^^21  days  later,  the  Court 
in  dealmg  with  a  totally  different  problem  creates  the  impression  by, 
its  repeated  references  to  the  Appalachian  Coals  case  ^^  that  the 
absence  of  monopoly  power  may  save  a  combination  which  otherwise 
would  be  unlawful.     Mr.  Justice  Stone  states: 

*  *  *  In  the  cases  considered  by  this  Court  since  the  Standard  Oil  case  in 
1911  some  form  of  restraint  of  commercial  competition  has  been  the  sine  qua  non 
to  the  condemnation  of  contracts,  combinations,  or  conspiracies  under  the  Sherman 
Act,  and,  in  general,  restraints  upon  competition  have  been  condemned  only  when 
their  purpose  or  effect  was  to  raise  or  fix  the  market  price.  It  is  in  this  sense  that 
it  is  said  that  the  restraints,  actual  or  intended,  prohibited  by  the  Sherman 
Act  are  only  those  which  are  so  substantial  as  to  affect  market  prices.  Restraints 
on  competition  or  on  the  course  of  trade  in  the  merchandising  of  articles  moving 
in  interstate  commerce  is  not  enough,  unless  the  restraint  is  shown  to  have  or  is 
intended  to  have  an  effect  upon  prices  in  the  market  or  otherwise  to  deprive  pur- 
chasers or  consumers  of  the  advantages  which  they  derive  from  free  compe- 
tition.    *     *     *  1$ 

*  *  *  So  far  as  appears  the  delay  of  these  shipments  was  not  intended  to 
have  and  had  no  effect  on  prices  of  hosiery  in  the  market,  and  so  was  in  that  respect 
no  more  a  restraint  forbidden  by  the  Sherman  Act  than  the  restriction  upon 
competition  and  the  course  of  trade  held  lawful  in  Appalachian  Coals,  Inc.,  v. 
United  States,  supra,  because  notwithstanding  its  effect  upon  the  marketing  of  the 
coal  it  nevertheless  was  not  intended  to  and  did  not  affect  market  prices. ^^ 

These  oscillations  of  opinion  thus  leave  unclear  the  precise  effect  accorded  the 
factor  of  market  control  in  loose-knit  confederation  cases. 

(C)   SUGGESTIONS 

The  statute  will  be  immeasurably  weakened  if  minority  groups  are 
permitted  to  eliminate  competition  among  themselves.  Such  ar- 
rangements inevitably  lessen  to  some  extent  the  competition  to  which 
the  public  looks  for  its  protection.  They  are  often  the  first  step  in 
a  program  of  monopoly  control.  Each  group  when  separately  con- 
sidered may  not  aft'ect  the  competitive  texture  of  the  industry,  but 
with  the  formation  of  each  additional  group,  competition  becomes 
rnore  and  more  attenuated  until  it  disappears.  Moreover,  these  com- 
binations are  normally  not  established  unless  competition  in  the  in- 
dustry as  a  whole  can  be  aft'ected.  The  only  justification  for  minority 
combinations  is  economic  self-defense,  when  unorganized  businessmen 
are  subjected  to  over-reaching  and  other  improper  practices  by  those 
with  whom  they  trade.  This,  however,  is  not  the  typical  situation 
in  industry. 

Courts  are  ill-equipped  to  apply  a  rule  which  is  more  economic 
than  legal  in  nature  and  which  necessitates  the  minute  examination 
of  many  subtle  factors.     An  erroneous  determination  by  the  Court, 

'0  Id.  at  225,  226,  n.  59. 

'1  (1940)  310  U.  S.  409. 

n  (1938)  288  U.  S.  344. 

'3  310  U .  S.  469,  500.  The  Court  cites  with  apparent  approval  the  decisions  in  the  Windou'  Glass  and  Chicago 
Board  of  Trade,  cases  and  also  the  various  merger  cases  in  which  combinations  not  controlling  the  market 
were  sustained. 

i<  Id.  at  501.    For  similar  passages  in  the  opinion  see  id.  at  492,  493,  n.  15;  495,  n.  16,  512. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  35 

exculpating  mcipient  monopolies,  will  have  dangerous  social  conse- 
quences. The  inadequate  and  sporadic  nature  of  judicial  control 
might  eventually  make  more  thoroughgoing  governmental  super- 
vision necessary.  No  suppression  of  competition,  however  minute, 
could  long  continue  without  such  regulation.  To  supervise  and 
regulate  the  multitudinous  arrangements  that  would  be  made  were 
the  dictum  of  the  Appalachian  case  ^^  to  become  the  established  rule 
would  impose  an  administrative  burden  upon  government  which  could 
only  be  justified  by  indubitably  clear  social  and  economic  gams. 

If  the  antitrust  laws  are  to  retain  their  potency,  vigilance  is  neces- 
sary to  prevent  their  attrition  by  nibbling  exceptions. 

In  our  opinion,  every  contract  or  combination  in  or  affecting  inter- 
state commerce,  between  two  or  more  persons,  to  eliminate,  prevent, 
impair,  or  lessen  in  any  degree  the  competition  between  the  parties 
thereto  or  among  any  persons  affected  thereby  should  not  be  permitted, 
save  possibly  under  very  special  circumstances  and  then  only  under 
effective   governmental   supervision. 

In  most  of  the  cases  before  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  the 
combinations  dominated  their  industries ;  in  the  few  cases  in  which 
predominant  control  was  lacking,  the  groups  nevertheless  possessed 
considerable  strength.  There  is  no  indication  in  the  orders  that  any 
distinction  is  being  drawn  by  the  Commission  on  the  basis  of  degree 
of  market  control. 

The  uncertainty  concerning  the  element  of  market  control  thus 
still  persists  and  can  only  be  finally  removed  by  legislative  action. 

PRICE  UNIFORMITY  AND  IDENTICAL  BIDS 

(a)  description  of  practice 

Price  uniformity  is  not  uncommon  in  many  industries.  Over  con- 
siderable periods  of  time,  virtually  the  same  price  may  be  quoted  by 
sellers  for  the  same  or  substantially  similar  products.  Such  prices 
may  be  constant  for  a  long  time,  or  they  may  fluctuate,  but  the 
fluctuations,  either  up  or  down,  tend  to  be  uniform.  Changes  will  be 
announced  or  placed  in  effect  at  substantially  the  same  time.  The 
movements  of  such  prices  do  not  harmonize  with  changes  in  the  gen- 
eral price  level.  The  unifoiTn  price  tends  to  be  rigid  or  "sticky"  when 
other  prices  are  rapidly  mounting  or  declining.  Its  rise  may  be  more 
rapid  or  its  decline  more  gradual  and  less  precipitate  than  prices  of 
related  goods.  This  uniformity  of  price  is  not  sporadic  or  inter- 
mittent; it  is  the  regular  and  noiTnal  procedure  in  many  industries. 

Sporadic  uniformity  may  occur  in  fields  characterized  by  the  widest 
diversity  of  price  and  price  movements.  Such  momentary  uniformity, 
if  not  typical  of  the  behavior  of  prices  in  the  industry,  raises  no  serious 
problem  under  the  antitrust  laws.  It  must,  however,  be  distinguished 
from  price  uniformity  which  is  prolonged  and  continuous. 

Uniformity  also  characterizes  the  prices  in  the  open  markets  main- 
tained on  organized  exchanges.  Everyone  buys  and  sells  at  the 
market  price,  which  is  liiglily  sensitive  to  market  conditions  and 
which  represents  a  temporary  truce  in  the  clash  of  the  opposing  forces 
of  buyers  and  sellers.  But  such  prices  are  extremely  fluid  and  change 
with  great  frequency,  sometimes  with  almost  every  sale.     Such  uni- 

is  (1933)  288  U.  S.  344. 


35  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

formity  as  may  obtain  at  any  moment  in  such  markets  manifests  the 
perfection  rather  than  any  imperfection  of  competition. 

Uniformity  or  identity  of  price  frequently  occurs  in  the  case  of 
competitive  bids.  In  recent  years  there  have  been  many  instances  of 
bids  submitted  to  pubhc  and  private  purchasers  which  were  identical 
to  the  last  penny. 

Although  it  is  essential  to  draw  a  sharp  distinction  between  sporadic 
and  constant  uniformity  in  fields  in  which  price  is  determined  by 
direct  negotiation  between  buyer  and  seller  in  each  transaction,  there 
is  no  need  for  a  similar  distinction  in  the  case  of  competitive  bids. 
Bids  are  submitted  in  response  to  a  specific  invitation;  they  are  con- 
cerned with  a  definite  transaction.  Identity  of  bids  is  seldom  a  mere 
fortuitous  occurrence  or  the  product  of  natural  economic  causes,  as 
may  be  the  case  of  sporadic  uniformity  in  a  fluctuating  market.  Such 
identity  bespeaks  collusion;  it  is  an  abnormal  condition  which  is  not  to 
be  anticipated  in  an  industry  truly  competitive. 

Uniformity  or  identity  does  not  connote  in  this  context  that  the 
prices  of  competitors  are  invariably  the  same.  It  is  sufficient  if,  con- 
sidering all  the  circumstances,  the  prices  or  bids  are  substantially  alike 
or  virtually  identical.  In  other  words,  slight  variations  or  studied 
differences  do  not  negate  uniformity  or  identity,  but  the  degree  of 
variation  must  necessarily  be  limited. 

(B)    ANALYSIS    OF    PRICE    UNIFORMITY 

It  is  a  curious  paradox  that  uniformity  of  price  may,  under  diverse 
circumstances,  be  a  token  both  of  perfect  competition  and  of  collusive 
restraint.  Under  conditions  of  perfect  competition,  with  products 
standardized  and  undift'erentiated,  sellers  numerous  and  of  approxi- 
mately equal  economic  strength,  and  buyers  fully  informed  concerning 
the  conditions  of  the  market,  uniformity  from  moment  to  moment  is 
to  be  anticipated.  That  is  not  to  say,  however,  that  under  con- 
ditions of  perfect  competition,  prices  are  maintained  without  modifica- 
tion over  considerable  periods  of  time  or  that  there  is  a  complete 
uniformity  in  the  fluctuations  of  the  prices  of  all  sellers. 

The  conditions  of  perfect  competition  characterize  the  ideal  market 
so  frequently  encountered  in  the  books  and  so  rarely  found  in  actual 
business  life.  Except  for  organized  exchanges,  most  markets  do  not 
conform  to  the  ideal  pattern  of  perfect  competition.  Products  may 
be  intricate  and  unstandardized ;  they  are  dift'erentiated  by  trade- 
marks, trade  names,  and  similar  symbols,  and  by  variations  in  quality 
and  other  characteristics.  Information  percolates  slowly  through 
most  markets ;  there  are  disparities  of  knowledge  of  market  conditions 
between  selhu-  and  buyer;  few  buyers  are  adequately  informed  con- 
cerning available  supplies  and  quotations;  sellers  are  limited  in  number 
and  some  producers  may  be  sufficiently  powerful  to  affect  the  market 
price  by  their  independent  action;  there  is  no  uniformity  on  the  part 
of  businessmen  as  to  then-  margins  of  profit  or  volume  of  business; 
disorganized  buyers  may  be  confronted  with  highly  organized  sellers. 
Uniformity  of  price  in  the  face  of  such  rich  diversities  of  product  and 
other  market  factors,  especially  when  prolonged  or  when  the  move- 
ment of  prices  is  contrary  to  general  economic  trends,  is  neither  natural 
nor  accidental;  it  is  an  artificial  condition  induced  by  coflusive  restraint. 
To  mistake  such  uniformity  for  the  perfection  of  competition  is  to 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  37 

confuse  the  perfect  competition  of  the  books  with  the  imperfect  com- 
petition of  the  market  place. 

(C)    STATE  OF  THE  AUTHORITIES 

The  Supreme  Court  has  indicated  that  uniformity  of  price  may  be 
evidence  from  which  an  unlawful  price  agreement  may  be  inferred.^* 
Such  uniformity,  however,  has  not  been  deemed  conclusive  proof  of 
collusion;  it  is  but  one  of  the  facts  tending  to  prove  the  existence  of  an 
unlawful  arrangement  concerning  prices.  The  Court  has  iieeded  the 
teachings  of  classical  economists  that  uniformity  is  a  symptom  of 
perfect  competition,  without  always  taking  into  account  the  actual 
competitive  texture  of  the  market  in  which  the  uniformity  occurs. 

In  Cement  Mfrs.  Protective  Assn.  v.  United  States,^'^  evidence  was 
introduced  that  the  prices  charged  for  cement  were  substantially 
uniform.  In  considering  the  effect  of  this  proof  on  the  legality  of  the 
collection  and  dissemination  of  trade  statistics  by  an  association,  the 
Court  stated: 

It  is  urged  by  the  defendants  that  such  uniformity  of  price  as  existed  in  the 
trade  was  due  to  competition.  They  offered  much  evidence  tending  to  show 
complete  independence  of  judgment  and  of  action  of  defendants,  by  large  expendi- 
tures in  competitive  sales  efforts  and  by  variations  in  the  volume  of  their  produc- 
tion and  shipment,  earnings  and  profits.  A  great  volume  of  testimony  was  also 
given  by  distinguished  economists  in  support  of  the  thesis  that,  in  the  case  of  a 
standardized  product  sold  wholesale  to  fully  informed  professional  buyers,  as 
were  the  dealers  in  cement,  uniformity  of  price  will  inevitably  result  from  active, 
free,  and  unrestrained  competition;  and  the  Government  in  its  brief  concedes  that 
"undoubtedly  the  price  of  cement  would  approach  uniformity  in  a  normal  market 
in  the  absence  of  all  combinations  between  the  manufacturers." 

We  realize  also  that  uniformity  of  price  may  be  the  result  of  agreement  or 
understanding,  and  that  an  artificial  price  level  not  related  to  the  supply  and 
demand  of  a  given  commodity  may  be  evidence  from  which  such  agreement  or 
understanding,  or  some  concerted  action  of  sellers  operating  to  restrain  commerce, 
may  be  inferred.  But  here  the  Government  does  not  rely  upon  agreement  or 
understanding,  and  this  record  wholly  fails  to  establish,  either  directly  or  by 
inference,  any  concerted  action  other  than  that  involved  in  the  gathering  and 
dissemination  of  pertinent  information  with  respect  to  the  sale  and  distribution 
of  cement  to  which  we  have  referred;  and  it  fails  to  show  any  effect  on  price  and 
production  except  such  as  would  naturally  flow  from  the  dissemination  of  that 
information  in  the  trade  and  its  natural  influence  on  individual  action. i^ 

In  determining  whether  competitive  conditions  existed  in  the  agri- 
cultural implement  industry,  the  Supreme  Court  in  United  States  v. 
International  Harvester  Co.,^^  found  that  many  of  the  competitors  of  the 
International  Harvester  Co.,  which  controlled  about  G4  percent  of  the 
business  in  this  industry,  were — • 

accustomed,  independently  and  as  a  matter  of  business  expediency,  to  follow 
approximately  the  prices  at  which  it  has  sold  its  harvesting  machines;  *  *  * 
and  the  fact  that  competitors  may  see  proper,  in  the  exercise  of  their  own  judgment, 
to  follow  the  prices  of  another  manufacturer,  does  not  establish  any  suppression  of 
competition  or  show  any  sinister  domination.^*^ 

16  See  Cement  Mfrs.  Protective  Assn.  v.  United  States,  (1925)  268  U.  S.  588,  606;  cf.  United  States  v.  United 
States  Sled  Corp.,  (1920)  251  U.  S.  417,  448,  449;  United  States  v.  International  Harvester  Co.,  (1927)  274  U.  S. 
693,  708. 

Bibliography:  Bums,  tlie  Decline  of  Competition  (1936),  ch.  V;  Dennison  and  Qalbraith,  Modem  Com- 
petition and  Business  Policy  (1936),  generally;  Lyon  and  Abramson,  the  Economics  of  Open  Price  Systems 
(1936),  ch.  IV;  Federal  Trade  Commission,  Open-Price  Trade  Associations  (1929),  especially  pp.  355  ct  seq.; 
Fly,  Observations  on  the  Antitrust  Laws  (1936),  45  Yale  L.  J.  1339. 

n  (1925)  268  U.  S.  588. 

18  Id.  at  606. 

i»  (1927)  274  U.  S.  693. 

28  Id.  at  708. 


3§  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

This  statement  conformed  to  the  Court's  earlier  pronouncement  in 
United  States  v.  United  States  Steel  Corp}^  The  issue  in  this 
case  was  not  whether  a  price  agreement  had  been  made  by  the  members 
of  the  steel  industiy  but  whether  the  Steel  Corporation  constituted  an 
unlawful  monopoly.  In  considering  the  competitive  position  of  the 
Steel  Corporation,  the  Court  refused  to  regard  the  fact  that  prices  in 
the  industry  had  been  uniform  or  that  competitors  had  followed  the 
corporation's  price  leadership  as  proof  of  monopoly  power.  It  rejected 
the  contention  that — 

when  prices  are  constant  through  a  definite  period  an  artificial  influence  is  indi- 
cated; if  they  vary  during  such  a  period  it  is  a  consequence  of  competitive  con- 
ditions. It  iias  become  an  aphorism  that  there  is  danger  of  deception  in  generali- 
ties, and  in  a  case  of  this  importance  we  should  have  something  surer  for  judgment 
than  speculation,     *     *     *P 

It  is  evident  that  the  Court  misapprehended  the  Government's 
contention  that  price  uniformity  manifested  monopoly  domination. 
In  holding  that  the  monopoly  provision  of  the  statute  had  not  been 
violated,  the  Court  did  not  rule  upon,  and  indeed  had  no  occasion 
to  pass  upon,  the  probative  force  of  uniformity  in  establishing  a 
collusive  agreement. 

As  the  Sherman  law  merely  forbids  contracts,  combinations,  or 
conspiracies  in  restraint  of  trade,  it  has  not  been  enough  for  the 
Government  to  show  in  any  litigation  that  conditions  exist  in  an 
industry  which  are  inconsistent  with  the  maintenance  of  competition. 
It  has  had  further  to  show  that  these  conditions  have  been  induced 
by  some  agreement  or  understanding.  Tliis  it  may  do  by  proof  of  an 
actual  agreement  or  of  facts  from  which  such  agreement  may  be  in- 
ferred. Under  the  decisions,  uniformity  is  clearly  one  of  the  facts 
from  which  the  inference  of  agreement  may  be  drawn,  but  it  is  not 
conclusive  evidence  of  a  collusive  agreement.  Although  there  is  no 
decision  holding  such  evidence  to  be  prima  facie  proof  of  collusion, 
it  must  be  noted  that  no  decision  has  expressly  refused  to  accord  the 
evidence  such  weight.  And  one  recent  decision  has  intimated  that 
uniformity  may  be  exceedingly  weighty  under  certain  circumstances. 
Thus  the  Court  in  Interstate  Circuit  Co.,  Inc.,  v.  United  States  ^^  said: 

It  taxes  credulity  to  believe  that  the  several  distributors  would,  in  the  circum- 
stances, have  accepted  and  put  into  operation  with  substantial  unanimity  such 
far-reaching  changes  in  their  business  methods  without  some  understanding  that 
all  were  to  join,  and  we  reject  as  beyond  the  range  of  probability  that  it  was  the 
result  of  mere  chance.^^ 

The  weight  of  such  evidence  should  be  further  clarified  in  the  decisions 
of  several  pending  cases.  Such  decisions  may  obviate  the  need  of  any 
legislation. 

(d)  suggestions 

The  limited  effect  accorded  proof  of  price  uniformity  under  the  rule 
laid  down  by  the  Supreme  Court  adds  to  the  difficulty  of  enforcing 
the  Sherman  law.  As  conspirators  typically  take  care  to  leave  no 
record  of  their  activities  and  avoid  reducing  to  writing  their  unlawful 
arrangements,  the  conspiracy  can  only  be  proved  by  circumstantial 
evidence.  In  many  cases,  the  Government  can  merely  establish  uni- 
formity of  price  or  identity  of  bids.     While  there  is  always  a  strong 

SI  (1920)  251  U.  S.  417. 

"  Id.  at  448. 

«  (1939)  30G  U.  S.  208,  discussed  in  23  Minn.  L.  Rev.  689;  52  Harv.  L.  Rev.  846. 

••(1939)  300  U.  S.  208,  223. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  39 

probability  that  iiniforinily  is  the  result  of  collusion,  it  may  bo  impossi- 
ble to  adduce  additional  legal  proof  of  direct  price-fixini?.  Unaided  by 
any  presumption,  the  Government's  suit  must  fail,  and  the  public  is 
thus  deprived  of  the  benefits  of  competition  in  the  many  instances  in 
which  collusion  is  in  fact  secretly  practiced. 

It  would  obviously  be  unwise  to  adopt  legislation  making  proof  of 
price  uniformity  conclusive  evidence  of  an  illegal  agreement  to  fix- 
prices  or  eliminate  competition,  in  view  of  the  diverse  circumstances 
and  innocent  occasions  in  which  uniformit}^  niay  occur.  A  statutory 
presumption,  however,  which  could  be  rebutted  by  appropriate  evi- 
dence showing  the  causes  of  uniformity  to  be  other  than  that  of  a 
collusive  agreement,  would  greatly  facilitate  the  enforcement  of  the 
statute  without  imposing  any  unfair  burden  on  persons  charged  with 
a  violation  of  the  law.  Such  a  presumption  would  merely  effect  a 
more  equitable  division  of  the  evidential  burdens  of  antitrust  litigation. 
Its  principal  effect  would  be  to  compel  those  in  a  position  to  know  the 
facts  to  come  forward  and  explain  the  reasons  for  the  continuous  uni- 
formity of  prices. 

To  invoke  a  presumption  of  collusive  agreement  in  every  instance  of 
uniformity  would  not  be  wise.  As  we  have  seen,  uniformity  may 
occur  in  highly  competitive  industries.  There  are  numerous  forces 
at  work  in  retailing,  for  example,  which  induce  uniformity  entirely 
apart  from  any  collusive  restraint.  Some  limitations  must  therefore 
be  placed  on  the  occasions  when  the  presumption  may  be  invoked. 
In  drafting  the  presumption,  the  objective  should  be  to  exclude  that 
uniformity  which  is  more  likely  the  product  of  natural  causes  and  to 
include  those  instances  of  uniformity  in  which  it  is  probable  that  there 
was  or  is  collusion.  Considerations  of  fairness  and  convenience 
should  determine  the  point  at  which  the  line  is  to  be  drawn.  This 
being  the  distinction,  it  is  impossible  to  draw  perfectly  the  line 
separatmg  these  two  types  of  uniformity.  This  undoubtedly  means 
that  some  instances  of  collusion  will  be  excluded  from  the  operation 
of  the  presumption,  but  such  exclusion  does  not  clothe  the  conduct  with 
any  immunity.  The  Government,  unaided  by  any  presumption,  may 
still  challenge  and  prove  the  concert  of  action  by  which  uniform  prices 
were  set.  On  the  other  hand,  the  presumption  may  embrace  conduct 
which  is  essentially  innocent.  It  is  for  this  reason  that  the  presump- 
tion is  a  rebuttable  and  not  a  conclusive  one.  By  appropriate  evi- 
dence, the  normal  inferences  from  uniformity  can  be  negated  and  the 
true  explanation  presented. 

The  existence  of  an  illegal  restraint  is  highly  probable  where 
uniformity  is  prolonged,  constant,  and  continuous,  where  miiformity 
has  persisted  during  periods  when  material  changes  in  demand  have 
occurred  or  when  there  have  been  substantial  changes  in  the  prices  in 
related  industries,  trades,  or  lines  of  commerce  or  in  the  general  price 
level,  or  where  prices  are  uniformly  maintained  at  a  set  level  despite 
a  marked  decline  in  related  prices  or  in  the  general  price  level,  or 
where  the  prices  of  unstandardized  and  undifferentiated  products  are 
identical.  To  hedge  the  presumption  with  numerous  qualifications 
would  greatly  impair  its  utility  and  defeat  its  purpose  by  requiring  a 
prelmiinary  factual  determination  by  the  court  as  difficult  as  the 
proof  of  the  disputed  price-fixing  agreement.  The  characteristic 
features  of  the  uniformity  of  price  and  price  movements,  wdiich  are 
highly  probative  of  collusion,  are  its  regularity,  constancy,  and  pro- 


4Q  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

longed  character.  Consequently,  a  presumption  arising  only  when 
the  uniformity  is  prolonged  and  constant  will  include  the  principal 
situations  in  which  artificial  restraints  occur,  and  exclude  the  main 
instances  in  which  uniformity  is  the  product  of  natural  causes.  The 
relationship  of  price  to  changes  in  demand  and  to  the  level  and  move- 
ment of  prices  in  related  industries,  as  well  as  other  explanatory 
factors,  may  be  inquired  into  on  rebuttal. 

The  distinction  between  continuous  and  momentary  uniformity  has 
no  application  to  bids  submitted  by  sellers  or  buyers  in  response  to  a 
specific  invitation.  Substantial  identity  in  such  a  case,  regardless  of 
any  disparity  in  the  prices  of  the  bidders  in  other  transactions,  is 
highly  suggestive  of  collusion  and  should  be  the  occasion  for  a  rebutt- 
able presumption  of  illegality. 

Neither  presumption  should  be  deemed  rebutted  by  slight  and 
studied  differences  of  price  quotations,  or  by  any  arrangement  whereby 
one  or  two  bids  are  placed  out  of  line. 

It  is  our  conclusion  that  the  rules  laid  down  by  the  Supreme  Court 
concerning  the  probative  force  of  evidence  of  uniformity  of  price 
should  be  changed.  Proof  of  a  price  uniformity  which  is  constant 
and  prolonged  should  give  rise  to  a  rebuttable  presumption  that  such 
uniformity  is  the  result  of  an  unlawful  contract,  combination,  or  con- 
spiracy in  restraint  of  trade.  The  presumption  should  not  apply  to 
sales  on  open  exchanges  which  are  subject  to  State  or  Federal  regula- 
tion. 

A  rebuttable  statutory  presumption  should  also  be  formulated 
makhig  proof  of  identity  of  bids  on  both  public  and  private  contracts 
presumptive  evidence  of  an  unlawful  contract,  combination,  or  con- 
spiracy in  restraint  of  trade. 

Additional  safeguards  against  collusion  in  bids  for  governmental 
contracts  can  be  erected  in  special  legislation  dealing  with  such  con- 
tracts. 

PRICE  LEADERSHIP 

(A)    ANALYSIS  OF  PRACTICE 

Price  leadership  has  supplanted  the  price-fixing  agreement  in  many 
industries  as  the  principal  device  by  which  prices  are  stabilized.  Like 
direct  price-fixing,  the  object  and  effect  of  the  practice  is  the  establish- 
ment of  a  noncompetitive  market  price.  This  end,  however,  is 
achieved  without  any  agreement  or  understanding.  The  price  an- 
nouncement of  one  of  the  companies  in  the  field,  typically  the  dommant 
concern,  or  principal  producer,  is  loyally  followed  by  most  of  its 
competitors.  The  price  leader  sets  the  market  price.  It  assumes  the 
lead  both  in  advancing  and  reducing  prices.  Administrative  action 
of  one  seller,  and  not  the  competition  among  sellers  and  the  higgling 
between  buyer  and  seller,  determines  the  market  price. 

Price  leadership  occiu's  primarily  in  industries  in  which  there  are 
but  a  limited  number  of  sellers.  It  is  not  feasible  in  the  atomistic 
industries  in  which  there  are  numerous  producers. 

An  agreement  among  competitors  to  sell  at  the  price  set  by  a  member 
of  the  industry  would  be  in  clear  contravention  of  the  statute.  Price 
leadership,  however,  is  rarely  encompassed  by  any  agreement  or 
understanding,  but  exists  typicall}'^  as  the  result  of  convention.  Each 
producer  waits  for  the  announcement  of  the  leader's  price  before 
publishing  his  own  price.     There  need  be  no  meetings,  no  discussions, 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  4]^ 

no  direct  interchange  of  price  information,  no  exchange  of  assurances, 
no  commitments  to  adhere  to  any  announced  price  for  the  practice 
to  take  root  in  an  iiuhistry.  In  other  words,  all  the  ingredients  of 
an  agi-eement  may  be  absent,  or,  if  present,  they  may  be  so  shrewdly 
concealed  that  discovery  is  virtually  impossible. 

If  the  leadership  is  to  be  followed,  the  price  must  be  placed  at  a 
level  which  is  attractive  to  the  other  companies  in  the  field,  or  the 
leader  must  possess  sufficient  power  to  compel  the  observance  of  its 
prices  by  competitors  fearful  of  reprisals. 

Complete  uniformity  does  not  always  exist;  in  many  fields  in  which 
price  leadership  occurs  there  are  occasional  variations  in  the  prices  of 
competitors  as  well  as  secret  "shading"  and  discrimination  of  price. 

Price  uniformity  is  the  necessary  consequence  of  price  leadership, 
except  where  the  leadership  is  partial  or  incomplete.  If  the  leader's 
prices  are  stationary,  the  price  structure  of  the  industry  tends  to 
become  rigid.  Fluctuations  in  the  leader's  price  provide  only  that 
degree  of  flexibility  which  the  leader  is  prepared  to  vouclisafe  the 
industry.  It  is  not  the  flexibihty  wdiich  results  from  the  individual 
responses  of  buyers  and  sellers  in  an  unrestrained  market  and  through 
wliich  supply  may  be  equated  with  demand.  It  is  a  controlled  flexi- 
bility, which  may  or  may  not  hamionize  with  changes  in  the  general 
price  level.  Dictation,  and  not  competition,  determines  price,  despite 
the  fact  that  the  followers  may  be  free  from  the  compulsions  of  an 
agreement  or  economic  pressure. 

Price  dictatorships,  like  other  forms  of  despotism,  may  be  benevolent 
as  well  as  tyrannical.  It  is  not  inconceivable  that  the  controlled 
price  of  an  enlightened  leader  may  be  economically  more  satisfactory 
than  the  haphazard  price  produced  by  the  blind  forces  of  compe- 
tition. Such  theoretical  possibilities,  however,  did  not  deter  the 
Supreme  Court  from  forbidding  price-fixing  agreements,  whether 
reasonable  or  not.  They  are  entitled  to  no  gi*eater  weight  in  apprais- 
ing the  desirability  of  price  leadership.  Private,  noncompetitive 
price-making  which  is  not  subject  to  any  effective  checks  and  balances, 
can  in  the  long  run  only  be  detrimental  to  the  public.  Price-making 
is  too  important  a  function  to  be  entrusted  to  the  uncontrolled  dis- 
cretion of  a  single  concern  or  a  group  acting  in  concert. 

Price  leadership  and  price-fixing  are  both  subject  to  the  same 
economic  and  administrative  objections.  The  price  set  by  the  leader 
tends  to  be  sufficiently  high  to  permit  the  continuance  in  business  of 
the  high-cost,  inefficient  producers.  It  exacts  a  toll  from  the  unor- 
ganized purchaser.  It  lacks  the  flexibility  and  resiliency  necessary 
to  mitigate  cyclical  economic  disturbances.  It  destroys  the  capacity 
of  the  business  system  to  adjust  itself  quickly  and  effectively  to  changes 
in  business  conditions.  It  increases  the  economic  pressure  on  un- 
controlled prices  and  thus  unbalances  the  entire  price  structure. 
It  unstabilizes  production  and  reduces  the  oi:)portunities  for  gainful 
employment.  The  sole  advantage  of  leadership  is  that  it  may  avoid 
wasteful  price  wars. 

The  only  dift'erence  between  direct  price-fixing  and  price  leadership 
is  that  group  control  of  prices  is  achieved  b}^  agreement  in  the  one 
case  and  by  convention  in  the  other.  If  the  consequences  of  a  non- 
competitive price  are  evil  when  established  by  agreement,  they  are 
equally  harmful  when  effected  through  tiio  tacit  acceptance  of  a 
leader's  price.     Unfortunately,  the  prohibitions  of  the  Sherman  law 

291144—41 — No.  38 4 


42  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

arc  limited  to  the  restraints  of  trade  accomplished  by  contract  or 
combination  and  do  not  extend  to  practices  equally  reprehensible 
which  do  not  involve  the  element  of  agreement. 

Leadership  is  not  limited  to  price  but  may  relate  to  production, 
distribution,  and  other  commercial  policies.  Wliat  is  said  in  the 
present  section  about  price  leadership  applies  equally  to  other  forms 
of  business  leadership. 

(b)  state  of  the  authorities 

The  legality  of  price  leadership  in  and  of  itself  has  never  been 
directly  tested  in  any  litigation  under  the  antitrust  laws.  Price 
leadership,  apart  from  any  agreement,  could  not  by  itself  constitute 
an  offense,  since  it  is  neither  a  contract,  combination,  or  conspiracy  in 
restraint  of  trade  nor  a  monopoly.  Its  significance  is  limited  to  its 
probative  force  in  proving  monopoly  or  a  conspiracy  in  restraint  of 
trade. 

In  the  only  two  reported  cases  in  which  evidence  of  price  leadershi]3 
was  adduced,^^  the  Government  sought  to  use  the  evidence  to  establish 
the  existence  of  a  monopoly.  In  both  cases,  the  Supreme  Court 
refused  to  draw  this  inference  from  the  proof. 

In  United  States  v.  United  States  Steel  Corp}^  in  considering  whether 
the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  was  exercising  monopoly  power 
and  suppressing  its  competitors,  the  Court  referred  to  the  evidence 
of  price  leadership  as  follows: 

Competitors,  it  is  said,  followed  the  corporation's  prices. because  they  made 
money  by  the  imitation.  Indeed  the  imitation  is  urged  as  an  evidence  of  the 
corporation's  power.  *  *  *  The  Government  does  not  hesitate  to  present 
contradictions,  though  only  one  can  be  true,  such  being  we  were  told  in  our  school 
books  the  "principle  of  contradiction."  In  one  competitors  (the  independents) 
are  represented  as  oppressed  b}^  the  superior  power  of  the  corporation;  in  the 
other  they  are  represented  as  ascending  to  opulence  by  imitating  that  power's 
prices  which  they  could  not  do  if  at  disadvantage  from  the  other  conditions  of 
competition;  and  yet  confederated  action  is  not  asserted.  If  it  were  this  suit 
would  take  on  another  cast.  The  competitors  would  cease  to  be  the  victims  of  the 
corporation  and  would  become  its  accomplices.  And  there  is  no  other  alternative. 
The  suggestion  that  lurks  in  the  Government's  contention  that  the  acceptance  of 
the  corporation's  prices  is  the  submission  of  impotence  to  irresistible  power  is,  in 
view  of  the  testimony  of  the  competitors,  untenable.  The}',  as  we  have  seen, 
deny  restraint  in  any  measure  or  illegal  influence  of  any  kind.-^ 

The  position  taken  in  the  Steel  case  was  reiterated  in  United  States 
V,  International  Harvester  Co}^  The  Court  there  found  that  many  of 
the  competitors  of  the  International  Harvester  Co.  were — 

accustomed,  independently  and  as  a  matter  of  business  expediency,  to  follow 
approximately  the  prices  at  which  it  has  sold  its  harvesting  machines;  *  *  *_ 
and  the  fact  that  competitors  may  see  proper,  in  the  exercise  of  their  own  judg- 
ment, to  follow  the  prices  of  another  manufacturer,  does  not  establish  Siwy  suppres- 
sion of  competition  or  show  any  sinister  domination.^" 

25  United  States  v.  United  States  Steel  Corp.,  (1920)  251  U.  S.  417;  United  States  v.  International  Harvester  Co., 
(1927)  274  U.  S.  093. 

BiblioRraphv:  Whitncv,  Trade  Associations  and  Industrial  Control  (1934),  131;  Marquand,  The  Dynam- 
ics of  Industrial  Combination  (1931),  175;  .Tones,  The  Trust  Problem  in  the  United  States  (1929),  225  #.; 
N.  R.  A.,  The  Operation  of  the  Basing  Point  System  in  the  Iron  and  Steel  Industry  (1935),  139;  Senate  Com- 
mittee, Keport  on  the  High  Cost  of  Gasoline  (1923),  41;  F.  T.  C,  Prices,  Profits,  and  Competition  in  the 
Petroleum  Industry  (1928),  F.  T.  C,  The  High  Prices  of  Farm  Implements  (1920);  Jones,  The  Anthracite 
Coal  Combination  in  tlie  United  States  (1914),  172;  F.  T.  C,  Newsprint  Paper  Industry  (1930);  F.  T.  C. 
Commercial  Feeds  (1924),  1921;  Whitney,  Trade  Associations  and  Industrial  Control  (1934),  129  #.;  Fetter, 
Masquerade  of  Monopoly  (1931),  202;  Sakolski,  Price  Making  and  Price  Stability  (1925)  SHarv.  Bus.  Rev. 
207. 

2«  (1920)  251  U.  S.  417. 

2'  Id.  at  447,  449. 

s«  (1927)  274  U.  S.  693. 

2»  Id.  at  708. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EC^ONOMIC  POWER  43 

In  neither  case  did  the  Court  oxpUcitly  reject  the  relevance  of  evi- 
dence of  price  leadersliip  to  the  proof  of  monopoly;  nor  did  it  intimate 
that  such  evidence  was  entitled  to  no  weight.  The  tenor  of  the 
opinions,  however,  is  that  the  fact  of  leadership  is  legally  unimportant 
in  determining  whether  the  leader  has  violated  the  monopoly  pro- 
visions of  the  statute. 

There  has  been  no  case  in  which  evidence  of  price  leadership  was 
offered  as  proof  of  direct  price-fixing.  There  is,  however,  authority 
to  the  effect  that  price  uniformity  is  to  be  treated  as  some  evidence  of 
a  price  agreement  to  be  considered  with  all  the  other  facts  in  the  case.^° 
By  its  language  in  the  Steel  ^^  and  Harvester  cases,^^  the  Court  did  not 
necessarily  mean  that  in  a  proper  case  evidence  of  price  leadership 
would  not  have  some  probative  effect  in  determining  whether  an  un- 
lawful agreement  had  been  made.  Price  leadership  is  some  evidence 
of  an  agreement,  to  be  considered  with  all  the  other  facts  of  the  case. 
There  can  be  no  doubt  that  where  uniformity  results  from  leadership, 
the  evidence  is  entitled  to  considerable  w^eight  on  the  issue  of  collusive 
restraint. 

(c)  sug'gestions 

The  prevalence  of  price  leadership  reveals  the  fundamental  wealaiess 
in  the  Sherman  Act.  A  law  which  prohibits  merelv  the  means  by 
which  evil  consequences  are  engendered  rather  than  the  consequences 
themselves  provides  an  easy  avenue  of  escape.  The  prohibitions  of  the 
Sherman  law  are  directed  against  the  elhnination  of  competition  by 
agreement  or  understanding.  The  act  is  powerless  to  prevent  the 
elimination  of  competition  by  other  means.  Uniform  price  and  pro- 
duction policies  can  be  pursued  without  resort  to  any  prohibited 
agreement.  Understandings,  if  there  be  any,  can  be  concealed  and 
remain  virtually  incapable  of  detection. 

Leadership,  of  course,  is  not  possible  in.  all  industries.  It  is  most 
effective  in  those  industries  in  which  there  is  concentrated  economic 
power,  in  which  competition  is  already  attenuated.  It  is  thus  chiefly 
used  in  areas  of  business  life  in  which  the  need  for  competition  is 
most  urgent.  No  believer  in  a  free  competitive  order  will  deny  the 
desirability  of  preventing  price  leadership  from  being  utilized  as  a 
device  to  eliminate  price  competition  in  our  concentrated  industries. 
The  difficulty  is  in  devising  ways  and  means  of  doing  so. 

An  outright  prohibition  of  price  leadership  as  such  is  not  feasible. 
Where  leadership  is  not  accomplished  by  agreement,  what  would  be 
the  precise  conduct  to  be  forbidden?  Businessmen  must  be  left  free 
to  meet  the  competition  of  their  rivals  and  this  may  involve  the  dupli- 
cation of  another's  prices.  Where  an  industry  is  ordered  to  abandon 
price  leadership,  what  in  practice  must  it  do  to  comply  with  the  order? 
The  leader  must  be  permitted  to  announce  its  price  at  some  time  even 
though  it  is  no  longer  the  first  to  publish  a  price  change.  Its  action 
may  still  be  followed.  The  dictates  of  business  judgment  may  require 
some  adherence  by  the  smaller  companies  to  the  price  schedule  of  the 
dominant  concern  in  the  industry.  An  order  directed  against  an 
agreement  is  objective  and  is  capable  of  enforcement  and  compliance. 
Any  prohibition  of  price  leadership  can  only  be  effective  if  it  is  directed 
against  conduct  which  is  similarly  objective. 

30  See  Cement  Mfrs.  Protective  Assn.  v.  United  States,  (1925)  268  U.  S.  588,  605. 

31  (1920)  251  U.  S.  417. 

32  (1927)  274  U.  S.  693. 


44  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

One  approach  might  be  to  eradicate  the  conditions  under  which 
leadership  flourishes.  Leadership  chiefly  occurs  in  the  ohgopohstic 
or  concentrated  industries.  To  remove  the  conditions  favorable  to 
leadersliip  would  entail  a  degree  of  pulverization  which  is  not  only 
impractical  but  would  cause  immeasurable  social  loss  and  impede  the 
program  of  national  defense.  Breaking  an  industry  of  5  units  into 
10  or  even  20  fragments  would  not  preclude  price  leadersliip. 

A  more  practical  approach  is  possible.  When  leadership  is  the 
result  of  agreement,  the  creation  of  a  statutory  presumpticm  of  ille- 
gality arising  from  proof  of  price  uniformity  would  compel  the  de- 
fendants to  come  forward  with  proof  peculiarly  within  their  control 
regarding  the  existence  or  nonexistence  of  a  collusive  agreement.  Such 
a  presumption  has  been  suggested  in  the  section  on  price  uniformity. 
To  make  leadership  'prima  jacie  evidence  that  the  leader  is  a  monopoly 
would  also  aid  in  discouraging  the  practice.  Leadership  by  a  smaller 
concern  is  unlikely  to  occur  except  as  part  of  an  agreement  with  the 
dominant  company  in  the  field,  and  would  be  covered  by  the  pre- 
sumption in  respect  of  price  uniformity.  Any  rule  which  drives  an 
industry  into  the  field  of  agreements  brings  it  within  the  scope  of  the 
statute. 

None  of  these  suggestions,  however,  will  materially  retard  the  price 
leadership  which  is  the  product  of  convention  rather  than  agreement. 
The  problem  can  only  be  dealt  with  by  administrative  action  designed 
to  ferret  out  the  causes  of  leadership,  eliminate  them  where  elimina- 
tion is  called  for,  and  generally  to  encourage  a  restoration  of  competi- 
tive conditions.  It  would,  of  course,  be  preferable  to  prohibit  directly 
those  acts  and  practices  which  produce,  encourage,  or  facilitate  leader- 
ship. There  is,  however,  no  unitary  cause  and  a  fixed  set  of  prohibi- 
tions could  easily  be  circumvented  by  a  new  set  of  practices.  Only 
by  a  flexible  administrative  procedure  can  the  present  causes  of  leader- 
ship be  outlawed  and  the  creation  of  new  devices  prevented. 

The  nature  and  extent  of  the  administrative  action  called  for  would 
necessarily  vary  from  industry  to  industry.  It  might  be  necessary 
in  some  fields  to  impose  restrictions  on  the  collection  and  dissemination 
of  price  data.  vSecrecy,  which  may  be  undesirable  in  highly  competi- 
tive industries,  may  actually  promote  competition  in  industries  charac- 
terized by  monopoly  conditions.  The  restrictions  imposed  by  the 
administrative  agency  must  not  prevent  sellers  from  meeting  the 
prices  of  rivals  in  fair  competition.  In  general,  the  agency  if  estab- 
lished must  bo  granted  broad  discretionary  power  to  regulate  and 
control  the  circumstances  making  for  price  leadership  and  formulate 
the  solutions  necessitated  by  the  occasion. 

It  would  be  the  function  of  the  administrative  agency  to  restore, 
invigorate,  and  protect  competition.  In  removing  the  causes  of 
price  leadership  it  will  encourage  the  smaller  companies  to  compete 
with  the  loader,  and  the  agency  must  stand  ready  to  ofl'er  protection 
against  reprisal.  The  abandonment  of  price  leadership  without 
administrative  supervision  and  protection  might  result  in  disastrous 
price  wars.  This  can  be  avoided  by  administrative  regulations  so 
conceived  as  to  eliminate  one  sot  of  evils  without  creating  others. 

Such  discretionary  administrative  supervision  involves  a  degree  of 
control  greater  than  has  been  traditionally  accorded  governmental 
agencies.  It  does  not,  however,  as  in  the  case  of  the  utility  regulation, 
mean  control  over  the  prices  to  be  charged.     It  is  regulation  directed 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  45 

to  a  specific  evil.  The  price  of  concentrated  power,  like  monopoly,  is 
governmental  reg-ulation.  What  is  here  said  of  price  leadership 
applies  with  equal  force  to  other  practices  and  business  methods, 
indigenous  to  the  concentrated  industries,  which  though  inconsistent 
with  the  proper  functioning  of  a  competitive  orchn-  are  outside  the 
reach  of  the  Shernuin  Act  because  they  are  not  brought  about  by  any 
agreement,  combination,  or  conspiracy.  A  sophisticated  and  well- 
advised  industry  avoids  the  crudities  of  the  familiar  restraints, 
achieving  its  ends  by  usages  of  the  trade,  which,  whatever  their 
genesis,  are  widel}^  accepted  and  observed  without  the  compulsion 
of  any  agreement.  Our  anti-trust  policy  must  fail  if  the  condemna- 
tion of  our  law  continues  to  bo  limited  to  the  elimination  of  com])etition 
by  agreement  or  understanding.  The  elimination  of  competition  by 
other  means  must  be  interdicted  and  a  positive  policy  formulated  for 
the  restoration  of  competition  in  those  industries  now  clniracterized 
by  industrial  folkways  antagonistic  to  free  competition. 

(D)    CONCLUSIONS 

In  order  to  prevent  price  leadership  to  the  fullest  extent  practicable, 
proof  of  price  leadership  should  give  rise  to  a  rebuttable  presumption 
that  such  leadership  is  the  result  of  collusion  or  monopoly,  and  indus- 
tries in  which  the  practice  is  prevalent  should  be  subjected  to  flexible 
administrative  regulation  designed  to  eliminate  the  causes  of  and 
conditions  favorable  to  the  practice,  and  to  restore,  invigorate,  and 
protect  competition  in  such  industries. 

MISCELLANEOUS  PRACTICES 

The  courts  have  passed  upon  the  legality  of  numerous  other  activi- 
ties of  trade  groups  besides  those  considered  in  the  previous  parts  of 
this  report.  Industry  has  become  well  versed  in  the  arts  of  restraint, 
and  the  amorphous  practices  in  which  it  currently  engages  are  still 
little  understood.  The  more  novel  restraint  is  probably  of  greater 
importance  today  than  the  traditional  restrictions,  but  the  paucity 
of  authority  precludes  any  extended  discussion  in  this  report.  The 
courts,  operating  under  the  broad  general  standard  of  the  Sherman 
Act,  have  shown  their  capacity  m  particular  litigations  to  outlaw 
those  activities  which  are  essentially  inconsistent  with  our  competitive 
institutions  while  sanctioning  practices  which  generally  operate  to  the 
advantage  of  the  public  as  well  as  the  industry.^^ 

The  current  program  of  vigorous  and  widespread  antitrust  enforce- 
ment should  lift  the  haze  which  enshrouds  many  comers  of  the  law. 
It  would  be  best,  pending  such  litigation  and  the  concomitant  widen- 
ing of  our  knowledge,  to  defer  any  legislative  treatment  of  these 
miscellaneous  and  novel  restraints. 

We  shall  consider  in  our  recommendations  the  approach  we  believe 
should  be  taken  in  respect  of  the  restraints  on  competition  resulting 
from  convention  and  the  usages  of  trade  rather  than  by  concerted 
action  and  agreement. 

Mention  should  be  made  m  passing  to  the  established  rule  that  the 
mvoluntary  exclusion  of  competitors  bj^  boycott  and  other  coercive 
measures  is  actionable.^*     The  Court  has  adhered  to  this  rule  without 


33  For  miscellaneous  activities  which  the  Court  has  sanctioned,  see  Maple  Flooring  Manufacturers'  Assn. 
V.  Vnifed  States  (1925),  268  U.  S.  563;  Cement  Manufacturers'  Protective  Assn.  v.  United  States  (1925),  268 
U.  S.  588;  Fly,  Observations  on  the  Anti-Trust  Laws  (1936),  45  Yale  L.  J.  1339,  1351  et  seq. 

2<  This  line  of  cases  covers  both  the  exclusion  from  as  well  as  the  entry  into  the  industry. 


46  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

deviation  during  the  entire  life  of  the  statute  and  has  outlawed  the 
boycott  no  matter  what  its  justification  may  have  been  and  regard- 
less of  the  beneficent  intentions  of  those  practicing  it.^^ 

The  restraints  practiced  by  the  labor  unions  now  being  challenged 
in  the  current  drive  by  the  Department  of  Justice  fall  outside  the  scope 
of  this  study  which  is  concerned  primarily  with  restraints  by  mdustry. 
It  is  sufficient  for  our  purpose  to  observe  that  the  cooperation  by  labor 
with  industry  in  the  elimination  of  competition  is  not  clothed  with 
any  exemption  and  is  on  a  parity  with  restramts  practiced  by  industry 
alone.  ^^ 

MERGERS  AND  CONSOLIDATIONS  '' 

The  combination  of  companies  is  probably  as  old  as  the  corporation 
itself,  but  the  merger  of  giant  organizations  in  building  large  in- 
dustrial empires  is  a  distinctly  modern  phenomenon.  The  earliest 
cases  in  this  country  involving  the  lawfulness  of  a  corporate  integra- 
tion date  from  the  late  eighties.  The  cases  are  relatively  sparse. 
There  is  no  reported  decision  on  the  problem  in  England;  the  number 
of  capital  combinations  passed  upon  by  the  Federal  and  the  State 
courts  is  relatively  small.  Only  the  Supreme  Court  decisions  will  be 
reviewed  in  this  section;  reference,  however,  will  be  made  to  the 
important  decisions  of  other  courts. 

1.    SUGAR    TRUST 

The  first  suit  under  the  antitrust  laws  to  reach  the  Supreme  Court 
was  a  merger  case.^^  Five  years  after  the  passage  of  the  Sherman  Act, 
the  Court  was  called  to  pass  upon  the  validity  of  a  series  of  mergers 
in  the  sugar  refining  industry.  Strictly  speaking,  these  were  not 
mergers  but  stock  acquisitions.  The  American  Sugar  Refining  Co., 
the  successor  of  the  Sugar  Refining  Trust,  purchased  with  its  own 
stock  all  the  stock  of  four  mdependent  refineries  located  in  Phila- 
delphia, which  together  produced  33}^  percent  of  the  sugar  refined  in 
the  United  States.  This  left  The  Revere  Co.  of  Boston,  with 
an  output  of  about  2  percent  of  the  total  domestic  production,  as  the 
sole  independent  refinery  in  the  country.  Thus,  as  a  result  of  these 
stock  acquisitions,  control  of  98  percent  of  the  industry  was  obtained. 
Prices  were  immediately  advanced.  The  suit  by  the  Government  was 
to  declare  void  the  contracts  for  the  exchange  of  stock,  to  compel 
the  return  of  the  stock  which  had  been  exchanged,  and  to  enjoin 
further  performance  of  the  agreements.  Relief  was  denied  on  the 
ground  that  the  challenged  transfers  related  merely  to  the  control  of 
manufacturing  as  distinguished  from  interstate  commerce  and  hence 
were  beyond  the  purview  of  the  Sherman  Act.  Under  the  Constitu- 
tion, it  was  pointed  out,  the  Congress  could  merely  forbid  restraints 

35  Paramount  Famous  Lasky  Corp.  v.  United  States  (1930),  282  U.  S.  30;  United  States  v.  First  National 
Pictures,  Inc.  (1930),  282  U.  S.  44;  Binderup  v.  Pathe  Exchange,  Inc.  (1923),  263  U.  S.  291;  Eastern  States  Retail 
Lumber  Dealers'  Assn.  v.  United  States  (1914),  234  U.  S.  600;  Fashion  Originators'  Guild  of  America,  Inc.  v. 
lederal  Trade  Commission  (1941),  9  U.  S.  L.  Week  4229.  Handler,  The  Sugar  Institute  Case  and  the  Present 
Status  of  the  Anti-Trust  Laws  (1936),  36  Col.  L.  Rev.,  1,  14. 

39  United  States  v.  Hrims  (1026),  272  U.  S.  549;  Local  167  v.  United  States  (1934),  291  U.  S.  293.  The  present 
rulings  of  the  Supreme  Court  defining  the  extent  to  whieh  the  anti-trust  laws  apply  to  the  acts  of  labor  units 
should  be  noted  at  this  point.  See  Apex  Hoisery  Co.  v.  Leader,  310  U.  S.  469  (1940):  United  States  v.  Hutche- 
son,  61  S.  Ct.  436  (1941). 

3'  The  author  has  in  this  section  drawn  upon  his  previous  writings.  See  Handler,  Industrial  Mergers 
and  the  Anti-Trust  Laws  (1932),  32  Col.  L.  Rev.  179;  Handler,  Cases  and  Materials  on  Trade  Regulation 
(1937),  .387.    T  he  compendious  footnotes  of  the  original  are  omitted. 

38  United  States  v.  E.  C.  Knight  Co.  (1895),  156  U.  S.  1. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  47 

upon  interstate  commerce;  monopolies  and  restraints  of  manufactur- 
ing or  of  production  wore  matters  of  State  and  not  Federal  regulation.'® 
It  is  thus  evident  that  this  was  no  decision  on  the  merits,  the  case 
going  off  on  constitutional  grounds. 

Hero  was  a  monopoly  of  an  important  necessity,  brought  about  by 
the  formation  of  a  trust,  which  was  succeeded  by  a  single  consolidated 
corporation,  and  followed  by  a  series  of  stock  acquisitions  b}"  which 
control  of  the  remaining  competitors  in  the  field  was  achieved.  Of  the 
monopolistic  purpose  and  intent  of  the  combining  companies  there 
could  be  no  question.  Competition  in  the  industry  had  been  com- 
pletely suppressed.  The  power  to  fix  a  monopoly  price  had  been 
acquired.  Whether  the  initial  trust  had  been  guilty  of  predatory 
practices  does  not  appear  in  the  Court's  opinion,  but  the  subsequent 
history  of  the  company  reveals  that  it  did  not  refrain  from  predatory 
methods  to  attain  its  ends.  Sources  extrinsic  to  the  Court's  opinion 
indicate  that  the  "trust"  was  heavily  overcapitalized,  that  generous 
profits  throughout  its  history  were  made  by  the  promoters,  and  that 
large  dividends  for  a  long  period  of  years  were  paid  upon  its  watered 
stock.  Its  inability  to  retain  its  control,  which  dwindled  from  98 
percent  in  1892  to  30  percent  in  1927,  casts  considerable  doubt  on  its 
economic  efficiency. 

Had  not  the  Supreme  Court  receded  from  its  extreme  position  w^ith 
respect  to  the  scope  of  the  Federal  power,  the  Sherman  Act  would  have 
been  without  effective  application  to  industrial  mergers. 

2.    NORTHERN    SECURITIES    CASE 

The  recession  began  within  less  than  a  decade  with  the  decision  in 
the  Northern  Securities  case.^  The  Northern  Securities  Co.  was  a 
New  Jersey  corporation  organized  by  the  Hill-Morgan  interests  to  hold 
stock  in  the  Northern  Pacific  Railway,  a  Morgan  road,  and  the  Great 
Northern  Railway,  a  Hill  road,  two  parallel  and  competing  lines  ex- 
tendmg  across  the  northwestern  tier  of  States  from  the  cities  of  Dulutli 
and  St.  Paul  to  Seattle  and  Portland. 

This  was  not  the  first  attempt  to  bring  these  roads  under  common 
control.  A  majority  of  the  bondholders  of  the  Northern  Pacific 
Co.  during  the  receivership  of  1893  had  arranged  witli  the  Great 
Northern  for  a  virtual  consolidation  of  the  two  systems,  control  passing 
to  the  latter  company.  The  Supreme  Court,  however,  in  Pearsall 
V.  Great  Northern  Railway, '^^  held  that  the  arrangement  violated  the 
Minnesota  statutes  forbidding  the  consolidation  of  competing  and 
parallel  railroads. 

Undeterred  by  this  decision,  the  two  companies  in  1901  acquired 
joint  control  of  the  Chicago,  Burlington  &  Quincy  Railway,  a  road 
extending  westward  from  Chicago  and  serving  as  a  feeder  for  both  of 
these  northern  railways  as  well  as  for  the  Union  Pacific  System,  w^th 
which  it  competed  in  part.  Harriman,  who  then  controlled  Union 
Pacific,  became  alarmed  at  the  acquisition  of  the  Burlington  stock  by 
Morgan  and  Hill,  and  in  self-defense  began  to  buy  into  the  Northern 
Pacific  Co.     So  skillfully  were  his  purchases  conducted  that  Harriman 

3»  The  opinion  was  delivered  by  Mr.  Chief  Justice  Fuller  for  a  Court  composed  of  Field,  Gray,  Brewer, 
Brown,  Shiras,  and  White.  JJ.  Mr.  Justice  Harlan  dissented  on  the  ground  that  under  the  prior  decisions 
of  the  Court,  commerce  included  not  only  transportation  but  also  acts  incidental  to  the  movement  of  goods 
across  State  lines,  such  as  the  production  of  articles  intended  for  interstate  commerce. 

«  Northern  Securities  Company  v.  United  Slates  (1904),  193  U.  S.  197.  The  majority  of  the  court  consisted 
of  Harlan,  Brown,  Day,  and  McKenna,  JJ.  Brewer,  J.,  concurred  in  a  separate  opinion.  White  and 
Holmes,  JJ.,  wrote  dissenting  opinions,  each  concurred  in  by  the  other  and  by  Fuller,  C.  J.,  and  Peekhara,  J. 

41  (1896)  161  U.  S.  646. 


4g  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

was  able  to  obtain  41,000,000  of  preferred  and  37,000,000  of  common, 
constituting  a  majority  of  the  capital  stock,  before  Morgan  became 
conscious  of  what  was  transpiring.  By  the  time  Alorgan  stepped  into 
the  market,  it  was  already  too  late. 

As  both  classes  of  stock  possessed  voting  power,  it  appeared  as 
though  Harriman  had  succeeded  in  wresting  control  of  the  Northern 
Pacific  from  Morgan.  But  under  the  articles  of  the  company  the 
preferred  issue  was  callable  at  par,  and  Morgan  controlled  the  com- 
pany. The  validity  of  this  provision  not  being  entirely  clear,  a 
compromise  was  inevitable.  The  compromise  took  the  form  of  the 
Northern  Securities  Co.,  to  which  the  chief  actors  in  this  financial 
drama  transferred  their  holdings  in  exchange  for  the  Northern  Securi- 
ties stock.  Stockholders  of  both  companies  were  invited  to  exchange 
their  stock  and  the  holding  company  subsequently  obtained  about 
nine-tenths  of  the  outstanding  Northern  Pacific  stock  and  more  than 
three-quarters  of  the  Great  Northern.  There  was  thus  practically 
no  pyramiding. 

The  suit  by  the  Government  was  to  rescind  the  stock  transfers  and 
to  compel  the  holding  company  to  divest  itself  of  the  stock  of  these 
competing  roads.  Despite  the  protestations  of  the  defendants,  the 
Court  found  that  the  purpose  and  effect  of  the  formation  of  the 
holding  company  was  to  suppress  competition  between  the  two 
systems,  and  ordered  the  dissolution  of  the  combination.^^ 

As  in  the  Knight  ^^  case,  the  combination  resulted  in  the  elimination 
of  competition  between  the  combining  companies.  But  here,  unlike 
the  Knight  case,  there  existed  an  active  competition  between  the 
combining  units  and  other  transcontinental  railroads.  This  fact  is 
generally  overlooked  in  discussions  of  the  case.  It  is  customary  to 
regard  the  Northern  Securities  Co.  as  controlling  two  natural  monopo- 
lies which  together  had  a  complete  monoply  of  the  northwestern 
railroad  business  and  the  decision  is  thus  easily  disposed  of.  But  as 
a  matter  of  fact,  the  overwhelming  proi^ortion  of  the  competitive 
business  of  the  two  roads — and  it  must  not  be  forgotten  that  only 
26  percent  of  their  total  earnings  was  derived  from  such  competitive 
traffic — was  itself  subject  to  the  competition  of  other  railroads.  The 
combination  brought  together  two  roads  possessing  in  part  a  natural 
monopoly  in  the  territories  tributary  to  their  separate  lines,  but 
competing  with  other  carriers  for  the  tlu-ough  traffic.     Only  a  minor 

<2  Four  opinions  were  written  in  the  Supreme  Court.  Justice  Harlan's  opinion  may  be  summarized  as 
follows:  (a)  The  Sherman  Act  declares  illegal  every  contract  or  combination  which  directly  restrains  inter- 
state trade,  whether  or  not  reasonable;  (b)  railroads  are  not  excluded  from  the  operation  of  the  act;  (c)  the 
holding  company,  like  the  trust,  restrains  and  monopolizes  trade  by  smothering  competition  for  the  mutual 
benefit  of  the  combining  units;  (d)  the  power  of  a  corporation  to  hold  stock  is  primarily  a  matter  of  State 
regulation,  but  where  the  ownership  of  stock  is  used  to  restrain  interstate  commerce,  the  Federal  authority 
prevails.  Justice  Brewer,  concurring,  pointed  out  the  dangers  of  holding  company  control  with  its  attend- 
ant pryamiding,  and  stated  that  while  an  individual  could  legally  procure  control  of  both  railroads,  a  cor- 
poration was  under  a  special  disability.  He  took  issue  with  the  view  of  the  majority  regarding  the  appli- 
cation of  the  rule  of  reason,  but  he  apparently  was  of  opinion  that  this  restraint  was  unreasonable.  Justice 
White,  in  his  dissenting  opinion,  contended  that  the  ownership  of  stock  is  not  interstate  commerce,  and 
hence  is  beyond  the  power  of  Federal  regulation.  He  regarded  as  untenable  the  majority's  distinction 
between  stock  ownershi))  by  an  individual  and  by  a  corporation.  Justice  Holmes  argued  that  a  holding 
company  does  not  fall  within  the  deOnition  of  contract,  combination,  or  conspiracy,  and  hence  is  not  covered 
by  the  statute.  The  contracts  forbidden  at  common  law  are  those  that  unreasonably  restrain  the  cove- 
nantor from  engaging  in  business;  the  forbidden  combination  or  conspiracy  relates  to  the  exclusion  of 
persons  from  the  trade.  The  present  case  involved  a  fusion,  not  a  contract;  there  was  no  evidence  of  any 
purpose  to  exclude  other  railroads,  hence  there  was  no  conspiracy.  See  Canfield,  The  Northern  Securities 
Decision  and  the  Sherman  Anti-Trust  Act  (1904),  4  Col.  L.  Rev.  315;  Bikl6,  The  Northern  Securities 
Decision  (1904)  52  Am.  L.  Reg.  358;  (1903)  3  Col.  L.  Rev.  404;  (1904)  4  Col.  L.  Rev.  287;  Morawetz,  The 
Anti-Trust  Act  and  the  Merger  Case  (1904),  17  Harv.  L.  Rev.  533;  Langdell,  The  Northern  Securities  Case 
and  the  Sherman  Anti-Trust  Act  (1903),  16  Harv.  L.  Rev.  539;  Canfield,  Is  a  Large  Corporation  an  Illegal 
Combination  or  Monopoly  Under  the  Sherman  Anti-Trust  Act?  (1909)  9  Col.  L.  Rev.  95 

"  (1895)  156  U.  S.  1. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  49 

part  of  the  business  for  which  the  two  roads  competed  was  free  from 
the  competition  of  other  carriers  and  only  with  respect  to  this  traffic 
was  competition  completely  eliminated. 

In  the  Sugar  case,'^^  the  combination  took  the  form  of  a  property 
owning  corporation  followed  by  stock  acquisitions;  here  a  holding  com- 
pany device  was  employed  to  unite  the  two  roads.  In  both  cases  there 
were  explicit  findings  that  the  purpose  of  the  combination  was  the 
suppression  of  competition.  There  w^ere  no  predatory  practices  either 
before  or  after  the  combine  was  formed.  It  must  be  remembered  in 
this  connection  that  the  regulatory  power  of  the  Interstate  Commerce 
Commission  was  very  limited  at  this  time.^^  In  view  of  the  expense 
and  difficulty  of  constructing  a  new  railroad,  potential  competition 
w^as  less  likely  than  in  the  sugar  refinery  field.  But  the  combination 
placed  no  obstacle  in  the  way  of  new  competition  and  in  1909  an 
independent  railroad  system,  the  Chicago,  Milwaukee  &  St.  Paul,  was 
constructed  across  the  same  tier  of  States.  Wliether  any  economies 
w^ould  have  been  effected  as  a  result  of  the  union  is  difficult  to  say; 
it  is  interesting  to  note  that  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  in 
1930  gave  its  approval  to  a  proposed  consolidation  of  the  two  lines. ^^ 
There  is  no  evidence  of  excessive  promoters'  profits  or  of  any  wildcat 
financing.  While  the  holding  company  was  capitalized  at  some  122 
millions  over  the  par  value  of  the  stock  of  the  two  roads,  the  value 
put  upon  the  securities  seems  to  have  been  no  higher  than  the  prevailing 
market  price. 

3.    OIL  AND  TOBACCO  TRUSTS 

The  dramatic  incidents  of  the  commercial  biographies  of  the 
Standard  Oil  and  American  Tobacco  companies  are  almost  household 
legends  and,  except  for  a  few  of  the  operative  facts  iin  the  two  dissolu- 
tion suits,  need  not  be  repeated  here.  There  were  three  stages  in  the 
creation  of  the  Standard  Oil  hegemony.  In  1870,  the  Standard  Oil 
Co,  of  Ohio  was  formed  with  a  capitalisation  of  $1,000,000  to  take  over 
the  partnerships  controlled  by  Rockefeller,  Andrews,  Harkness,  and 
Flagler.  The  union  of  these  partnerships  made  the  company  the 
largest  oil  refining  concern  in  the  industry  although  it  refined  only 
10  percent  of  the  country's  output  and  bad  some  250  competitors. 
By  1879  the  Ohio  corporation,  through  predatory  practices,  control 
over  pipe  fines,  and  railroad  rebates,  had  increased  its  control  from 
10  percent  to  about  90  or  95  percent,  having  either  driven  its  com- 
petitors out  of  business  or  having  forced  them  to  sell  out.  The 
concerns  so  acquired  w^ere  either  absorbed  by  the  Ohio  Company  or 
operated  as  ostensibly  separate  entities  under  the  names  of  their 

"  Ibid. 

45  See  1  Sharfman,  The  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  (1931),  19-40. 

<«  The  dissolution  decree  permitted  distribution  of  the  stock  of  both  Great  Northern  and  Northern 
Pacific  to  the  shareholders  of  the  Securities  Co.,  each  recipient  receiving  a  part  of  the  stoclc  of  the  two  roads. 
Harriman  objected  to  the  form  of  the  decree  inasmuch  as  it  split  up  his  block  of  Northern  Pacific  and  made 
him  a  minority  stockholder  in  both  roads.  His  objections  were  futile,  the  Supreme  Court  approving  the 
decree  drafted  bv  the  lower  court.  Harriman  v.  Northern  Securities  Company  (19(15),  197  V.  S.  244.  On 
August  3,  1921,  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  filed  its  tentative  plan  for  the  consolidation  of  rail- 
roads under  the  Transportation  Act  of  1920.  Under  that  plan  the  Northern  Pacific  and  Burlington  were 
placed  in  system  No.  14,  while  the  Chicago,  Milwaukee  and  the  Great  Northern  were  grouped  in  system 
No.  15.     63  I.  C.  C.  455,  461-462  (1921). 

This  arrangement  was  not  satisfactory  to  the  roads  concerned,  and  on  July  8,  1927,  the  Great  Northern 
Pacific  Railway  Company,  a  holding  company,  petitioned  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  to  per- 
mit it  to  acquire  control  of  the  properties  of  Great  Northern  and  Northern  Pacific  by  lease  and  stock  owner- 
ship. On  December  9,  1929,  the  Commission  issued  another  plan,  placing  these  roads  in  system  No.  12. 
159  I.  C.  C.  522,  538  (1929).  The  petition  of  the  Great  Northern  Pacific  Railway  Co.  was  decided  favorably 
to  the  petitioner  on  February  11,  1930,  with  two  Commissioners  dissenting.  162  I.  C.  C.  37  (1930).  How- 
ever, the  application  was  dismissed  on  February  19,  1931,  upon  icquest  of  the  applicants. 


5Q  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

former  owners.  The  consideration  for  these  purchases  was  chieflj^ 
stock  of  the  Ohio  Company,  sometimes  cash.  The  period  from  1882  to 
1899  was  the  period  of  the  Standard  Oil  Trust.  Under  the  management 
of  the  trustees,  the  holdings  were  reorganized  and  separate  Standard 
Oil  companies  were  formed,  to  which  the  business  in  pai'ticular  locali- 
ties was  allocated.  In  1892,  the  trust  was  adjudged  illegal  and  its 
dissolution  ordered  by  the  Supreme  Court  of  Oliio  in  a  quo  warranto 
proceeding  against  the  Standard  of  Ohio.*^  At  the  time  of  the  quo 
warranto  proceedings,  the  trustees  controlled  84  companies.  Pretend- 
ing to  comply  with  the  decree  of  the  Ohio  court,  they  transferred  the 
stock  of  64  of  the  companies  to  the  remainmg  20,  which  the  trustees 
still  controlled,  and  then  dissolved  the  trust.  The  attorney- 
general  of  Ohio  having  initiated  contempt  proceedings  in  1897,  it 
became  necessary  to  devise  a  new  method  of  controlling  the  industry. 
The  Standaid  Oil  of  New  Jersey,  an  operating  company,  had  been 
formed  in  1892  with  a  capitalization  of  $10,000,000.  In  1899  the 
charter  of  this  company  was  amended  so  as  to  empower  it  lo  hold 
stock  in  other  companies,  and  its  capitalization  was  increased  to 
$110,000,000.  Thereupon  an  exchange  was  effected  of  the  shares 
of  the  New  Jersey  company  for  those  of  the  companies  previously 
controlled  by  the  trustees.  The  New  Jersey  company  thus  became 
essentially  a  holding  company,  although  it  continued  to  operate  the 
refineries  it  had  owned  prior  to  the  reorganization.  The  formation 
of  the  New  Jersey  holding  company  marks  the  third  period  in  the 
history  of  Standard  Oil,  and  it  was  against  this  holding  company  that 
the  Government  in  1906  brought  its  suit  for  dissolution.^* 

The  percentage  of  the  industry  controlled  at  the  time  of  suit  is  not 
stated  in  the  court's  opinion.  In  1904,  however,  between  85  to  90 
percent  of  the  country's  output  was  refined  either  by  the  Standard 
Oil's  constituent  companies  or  by  companies  which  it  dominated.  The 
degree  of  control  had  not  decreased  in  the  following  years.  The  im- 
portant pipe  lines  in  the  country — the  strategic  center  of  the 
monopoly — were  under  its  control.  Although  the  production  of  crude 
oil  was  in  other  hands,  the  disorganized  and  highly  competitive  con- 
dition of  that  branch  of  the  industry  operated  to  the  advantage  of 
Standard,  which  was  practically  the  sole  purchaser.  This  monopol}^ 
of  the  oil  refining  business  had  been  acquired  as  a  result  of  the  prefer- 
ential rebates  exacted  from  the  railroads,  and  through  the  ruthless 
suppression  of  competition.  The  list  of  predatory  acts  practiced 
by  the  company  filled  some  57  pages  of  the  record.  Its  violation 
of  the  antitrust  laws  was  deliberate;  its  desire  to  obtain  a  monopoly 
and  to  exclude  competition  from  the  industry  is  evident  in  almost 
every  page  of  its  history.  The  spoils  were  enormous,  and  stock- 
holders were  given  a  goodly  share.  Though  the  holding  company 
was  adopted  as  the  device  for  effectuating  the  combination,  there 
seems  to  have  been  no  pyramiding,  and  the  company's  financial 
record  is  clear  of  undue  promoters'  profits,  extravagant  underwriting 
charges,  and  stock  frauds.  The  verdict  of  impartial  students  of  the 
subject  is  that  its  dominance  did  not  result  from  efficient  management 
and  economies  in  production,  but  rather  from  the  abuse  of  its  control 

<'  Slate  V.  Slundard  Oil  Company  (Ohio  1892),  30  N.  E.  279. 

<8  Stniuhird  Oil  ( \)iiipiiini  ofAU'ir  Jersey  v.  United  States  (1911),  221  U.  S.  1.  Mr.  Chief  Justice  White  wrote 
the  opinion,  holdiiiir  tiuit  tlie  dcfcnflants  had  violated  the  Sherman  Act  and  enunciating  the  famous  rule  of 
reason,  for  a  court  composed  of  McKcuiia,  Hohnes,  Day,  Lurton,  Hughes,  Van  Devan'ter,  and  Lamar,  JJ. 
Mr.  Justice  Harlan  concurred  in  the  dissdlution  of  Standard  Oil  but  disagreed  with  the  Chief  Justice's 
construction  of  the  statute.    For  the  final  decree  see  (C.  C.  Mo.  1909)  173  Fed.  177, 192. 


CONCKIVTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  51 

of  the  pipe  lines,  from  railroad  discriminations  and  unfair  methods  of 
competition.  Integiation,  the  location  of  refineries  near  the  source 
of  supplies,  and  large-scale  operation  were  productive  of  great  econo- 
mies; but  all  these  were  possible  without  monopolistic  control,  as 
has  been  amply  proved  by  the  growth  of  giant  competitive  petroleum 
companies  smce  the  dissolution  of  the  ''trust." 

The  Government's  case  was  so  strong  that  it  is  dilTicult  to  appraise 
the  legal  significance  of  the  numerous  facts  that  have  been  reviewed. 
Whether  the  case  turned  upon  the  fact  that  the  company  had  acquired 
monopolistic  power,  or  upon  the  existence  of  a  wrongful  intent  to 
monopolize  the  industry,  or  upon  the  indulgence  in  predatory  prac- 
tices and  the  exclusion  of  competitors,  or  upon  the  use  of  the  holding 
company  to  control  the  industry,  or  upon  the  combination  of  all  these 
features,  it  is  not  easy  to  say.  The  lengthy  opinion  of  Mr.  Chief 
Justice  White  is  more  concerned  with  the  profundities  of  the  rule  of 
reason  than  with  an  explicit  statement  of  the  grounds  of  decision.  The 
element  which  is  most  stressed  in  the  opinion  is  the  defendants'  intent 
to  monopolize  the  industry  and  to  maintain  their  monopoly  tlu'ough 
the  exclusion  of  competitors.*^ 

The  American  Tobacco  suit,^°  in  which  dissolution  of  the  combina- 
tion was  decreed,  ran  along  much  the  same  lines.  Here  again  is  the 
story  of  a  so-called  bad  trust  dominating  all  branches  of  the  tobacco 
industry,  manufacturing  at  the  time  of  suit  86.1  percent  of  the  coun- 
try's output  of  cigarettes,  91.4  percent  of  little  cigars,  96.5  percent  of 
snuff,  84.9  percent  of  plug,  76.2  percent  of  smoking  tobacco,  79.7  per- 
cent of  fine  cut  tobacco,  and  14.4  percent  of  cigars.  Purchases  of 
competing  companies,  dismantling  of  plants,  predatory  practices,  ex- 
clusion of  competitors,  restriction  of  potential  competition  by  the  uni- 
form practice  of  tying  up  the  sellers  of  the  acquired  companies  by 
agreements  not  to  compete  for  long  periods  of  time,  an  unmistakable 
intent  to  monopolize  the  industry,  which  in  the  main  was  successfully 
achieved,  concentration  of  control  of  the  companies  in  a  handful  of 
men,  tremendous  over-capitalization,  over-valuation,  enormous  profits, 
and  large  dividends — all  of  these  were  present.  That  the  combination 
so  dominated  the  industry  as  to  control  prices  and  that  the  competi- 
tion of  the  independents  was  generally  incft'ective  seem  reasonbly  clear. 
A  complete  monopoly  was  not,  however,  obtained. 

The  financial  history  of  the  various  combinations  eventually  result- 
ing in  the  formation  of  the  American  Tobacco  Co.  is  too  complicated 
to  be  reviewed  in  any  detail  here,  but  a  few  of  the  important  purchases 
can  be  enumerated.  The  original  American  Tobacco  Co.  organized 
under  the  laws  of  New  Jersey  was  a  consolidation  of  five  cigarette 
companies,  the  property  and  assets  of  wliich  were  conveyed  in  1890  to 
the  new  corporation  in  exchange  for  its  capital  stock.  The  original 
capitahzation  was  $25,000,000  wdiich  apparently  was  much  in  excess 
of  the  value  of  the  constituent  companies.     The  consolidated  company 

«  Upon  the  recent  merger  of  the  Standard  Oil  Co.  of  New  York  with  the  Vacuum  Oil  Co.,  the  Govern- 
ment filed  a  supplemental  bill  on  the  ground  that  the  original  decree  forbade  the  union  of  any  of  the  de- 
fendants. The  court,  however,  dismissed  the  bill,  ruling  that  the  combination  violated  neither  the  decree 
nor  the  Sherman  Act.  United  States  v.  Standard  Oil  Company  of  New  Jersey,  Standard  Oil  Co.  of  New  York, 
and  the  Vacuum  Oil  Company  (E.  D.  Mo.  1931),  47  F.  (2d)  288.  The  court  in  the  decision  specifically 
stated  that  it  was  not  deciding  that  all  former  Standard  Oil  Coniiianics  could  lawfully  conihme;  it  hmited 
its  holding  to  the  union  of  these  companies  and  rested  its  decision  on  the  particular  facts  there  involved.  It 
gave  much  consideration  to  the  nature  and  extent  of  competition  between  the  merging  companies  as  well  as 
as  to  the  competitive  situation  in  the  industry  at  large. 

511  United  States  v.  American  Tobacco  Company  (1911),  221  U.  S.  106.  The  alignment  of  the  justices  was  the 
same  as  in  the  Standard  00  decision.  The  Chief  Justice  wrote  the  opinion  for  the  Court,  ordering  the  dis- 
solution of  the  combination,  and  Mr.  Justice  Harlan  dissented  from  the  adoption  of  the  rule  of  reason. 


52  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

at  the  outset  manufactured  96  or  97  percent  of  the  domestic  output  of 
cigarettes.  It  soon  increased  its  capital  stock  and  branched  out  into 
the  allied  business  of  manufacturing  cigars,  smoking  tobacco,  and  snuff, 
constantly  buying  up  large  numbers  of  companies,  sometimes  for  cash, 
sometimes  for  stock,  or  a  combination  of  both.  In  1893,  an  attempt 
to  combine  the  leading  plug  tobacco  manufacturers  proved  unsuccess- 
ful. Then  followed  a  ruinous  price  war  wliich  cost  American  Tobacco 
about  $4,000,000,  but  which,  by  1898,  brought  its  competitors  to 
terms.  In  that  year  the  Continental  Tobacco  Co.  was  formed  with 
a  capital  of  $75,000,000,  later  increased  to  $100,000,000,  to  take  over 
the  assets  of  five  large  plug  manufacturers  and  the  plug  business  con- 
trolled by  American  Tobacco.  The  properties  were  exchanged  for 
Continental's  stock  and  for  cash,  and  were  greatly  overvalued.  Con- 
trol of  the  new  company  was  assured  by  Mr.  Duke,  president  of  Amer- 
ican Tobacco,  becoming  president  of  Continental,  and  by  American 
Tobacco,  receiving  $30,000,000  of  stock  for  its  plug  business.  This 
combination  made  American  Tobacco  an  important  factor  in  each  of 
the  various  fields  of  tobacco  products. 

American  Tobacco  in  preparation  for  fresh  conquests  doubled  its 
capital  stock  to  $70,000,000  and  declared  a  100  percent  stock  dividend. 
In  the  next  few  years,  American  and  Continental  acquired  30  compet- 
ing companies  at  an  aggregate  cost  of  $50,000,000.  In  all  these 
acquisitions  covenants  not  to  compete  were  systematically  required 
of  the  sellers.  Most  of  the  plants  so  purchased  were  shut  down  and 
never  operated  despite  the  disbursement  of  what  the  Court  terms 
enormous  sums.  Next  came  consolidations  in  the  snuff,  tm  foil,  cigar, 
licorice,  and  stogy  fields.  Following  the  American  Tobacco  tradi- 
tional method  of  combination,  a  corporation  was  formed  in  each  case, 
to  which  the  properties  of  the  important  independents  and  of  Con- 
tinental and  American  were  transferred  m  exchange  for  stock  in  the 
new  company.  In  some  instances,  the  consolidated  company  merely 
acquired  stock  in  the  sellmg  company.  Occasionally  a  purchase  of 
assets  carried  with  it  stock  in  nominally  independent  companies.  As  a 
result  of  these  acquisitions,  American  Tobacco  became  to  a  large  extent 
a  holding  company  of  the  stocks  of  its  affiliated  and  subsidiary  cor- 
porations. 

In  1901,  the  Consolidated  Tobacco  Co.  was  incorporated  in  New 
Jersey.  A  majority  of  its  shares  was  taken  by  Duke  and  his  associ- 
ates. Largely  in  exchange  for  its  bonds,  the  new  company  acquired 
substantially  all  the  common  stock  of  the  American  and  Continental. 
Consolidated  was  thus  a  pure  holding  company.  In  1904,  possibly 
because  of  the  decision  of  the  Supreme  Court  in  the  Northern  Se- 
curities case,^^  it  was  decided  to  reorganize  the  three  companies. 
American  Tobacco  was  recapitalized  at  $180,000,000  and  Continental 
and  Consolidated  were  dissolved,  the  assets  and  properties  of  the  com- 
panies being  transferred  to  the  merged  company,  the  new  American 
Tobacco  Co.,  the  chief  defendant  in  the  Government  suit.  The  stock 
in  the  new  company  was  so  distributed  as  not  to  disturb  the  control 
of  the  six  men  who  had  dominated  the  other  corporations,  American 
Tobacco  after  the  reorganization  was  both  an  operating  and  holding 
company. 

We  find  here  instances  of  almost  every  type  of  corporate  combina- 
tion that  has  ever  been  attempted — consolidation,  {.  e.,  acquisition  of 

"  (1904)  193  U.  S.  197. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  53 

assets  of  combining  companies  by  a  new  company  created  for  this 
purpose,  holding  company,  acquisition  of  stock,  and  merger,  i.  e., 
the  absorption  of  one  competitor  by  another  through  the  transfer  of 
assets  for  either  a  cash  or  stock  consideration  or  for  both.  The 
Northern  Securities  ^-  and  the  Standard  Oil  '^^  cases  had  declared  a 
combination  effected  through  the  holding  company' 'device  to  be  un- 
lawful; here  even  an  out  and  out  fusion  was  held  to  violate  the  Sherman 
Act.  The  Court  in  its  opinion  set  forth  at  length  the  details  of  these 
intricate  corporate  relationships,  but  it  seemingly  gave  little  weight 
to  the  forms  of  combination  employed.  In  no  uncertain  terms,  it 
pointed  out  that  the  wording  of  the  statute  was  broad  enough  to 
brmg  withm  its  condemnation  every  conceivable  act,  regardless  of  the 
"garb  in  which  such  acts  were  clothed,"  which  contravened  the  under- 
lying policy  of  the  statute.  It  rested  its  decision  essentially  upon  the 
ground  that  the  intent  and  purpose  of  this  long  series  of  combinations 
was  to  monopolize  the  tobacco  industry  and  to  stamp  out  competition. 
This  inference  the  Court  drew  not  from  the  size  of  the  consolidation, 
nor  from  the  number  of  acquisitions,  nor  from  the  dommation  of  the 
industry  which  thus  resulted,  but  from  the  following  facts:  (1)  that 
the  first  combination  was  impelled  by  the  fierce  trade  war  which 
immediately  preceded  its  formation,  (2)  that  the  consolidations  in  the 
various  fields  were  always  preceded  by  trade  conflicts  designed  either 
to  drive  competitors  out  of  business  or  to  force  them  to  enter  the 
combination,  (3)  that  the  manifest  purpose  of  the  small  coterie  who 
put  through  these  consolidations  was  to  obtain  control  of  the  industry 
and  to  retain  such  control  in  their  own  hands,  (4)  that  by  obtaining 
control  of  the  various  stages  in  the  manufacture  of  tobacco  products 
perpetual  barriers  to  the  entry  of  others  into  the  trade  were  thereby 
created,  (5)  that  millions  were  expended  in  buying  plants  which  were 
immediately  dismantled,  and  finally  (6)  that  covenants  not  to  com- 
pete were  systematically  obtamed  in  all  these  transactions. 

As  in  the  oil  suit,^*  the  case  is  complicated  by  the  presence  of  so 
many  factors  that  it  is  impossible  to  determine  with  any  assurance 
which  was  controlling.  The  Court  seems  to  give  paramount  impor- 
tance to  the  wrongful  intent  which  here,  as  we  have  seen,  is  inferred 
not  from  the  fact  of  monopoly  as  much  as  from  the  manner  in  which 
such  monopoly  was  obtained.  In  the  Standard  Oil  case,^^  the  infer- 
ence was  drawn  from  the  degree  of  control  which  the  combination 
was  able  to  exercise  as  well  as  from  the  other  factors  mentioned. 
We  shall  note  a  similar  oscillation  in  the  later  cases.  Before  leaving 
the  case,  the  Court's  emphasis  upon  the  restrictions  on  new  or  poten- 
tial competition  should  be  noted. 

4.    TERMINAL    CASE 

The  *S'^.  Louis  Terminal  case  ^^  dealt  with  a  "neck-of-the-bottle" 
monopoly.  The  topographical  position  of  St.  Louis  makes  its  ter- 
minal transportation  facilities  peculiarly  susceptible  to  monopoly 
control.     The  city  lies  upon  a  series  of  hills  which  hug  the  western 

»2  Ibid. 

"  (19U)  221  U.  S.  1. 

»i  Ibid. 

««  Ibid. 

56  United  States  v.  Terminal  Railroad  Association  of  St.  Louis  (1912),  224  U.  S.  383.  The  opinion,  written 
by  Justice  Lurton,  represented  a  court  composed  of  White,  C.  J.,  McKenna,  Hughes,  Van  Devantcr,  and 
Lamar,  JJ.  Holmes  and  Day,  JJ.,  took  no  part  in  the  decision  of  the  ca.se.  Mr.  Justice  Pitney  was  ap- 
pointed after  the  argument  but  before  the  publication  of  the  opinion. 


54  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

bank  of  the  Mississippi  River,  receding  rapidly  toward  the  west. 
These  hills  are  penetrated  on  the  west  by  the  narrow  valley  of  Mill 
Creek  which  crosses  the  city  at  about  its  center.  This  valley  forms 
the  sole  ingiess  for  railways  commg  from  the  West,  and  its  limited 
area  is  fully  utilized  by  the  western  roads.  The  approach  to  the 
city  from  the  north  on  the  western  side  of  the  river  is  through  the 
valley  formed  by  the  Missouri  and  Mississippi  Rivers,  the  hills  drop- 
ping back  from  the  water  at  this  pomt.  The  broad  Mississippi 
Valley  is  on  the  Illinois  or  eastern  side  of  the  river  and  it  is  in  this 
valley  that  the  roads  from  the  East,  Northeast,  and  Southeast  have 
their  termini.  Thus,  although  24  railroads  converge  at  St.  Louis, 
not  one  passes  through  the  city  or  connects  directly  with  the  others 
approaching  from  opposite  directions.  To  connect  these  roads, 
extensive  facilities  had  to  be  constructed,  the  river  spanned,  and  the 
western  hills  tunneled.  Cooperation  among  the  carriers  was  im- 
perative as  no  one  road  could  afford  to  construct  a  separate  terminal 
system,  and  the  topographical  condition  of  the  section  did  not  permit 
of  many  separate  systems. 

In  1889,  several  of  the  roads  acquired  the  properties  of  a  few  inde- 
pendent terminal  companies  for  the  purpose  of  combining  and  operat- 
ing them  as  a  unitary  system.  These  properties  included  the  union 
station,  the  Eads  or  St.  Louis  bridge,  the  only  railroad  bridge  over 
the  river  at  the  time,  and  extensive  trackage  on  both  sides  of  the 
river.  The  consolidated  company  was  known  as  the  Terminal  Rail- 
road Association  of  St.  Louis  and  was  jointly  owned  by  several  rail- 
roads, all  of  which  bound  themselves  to  use  these  facilities  exclusively. 
Under  the  agreement  by  which  the  Terminal  Co.  was  formed,  unani- 
mous consent  of  the  members  was  required  for  the  admission  of  new 
roads  or  the  use  of  its  properties  by  non-member  roads.  The  restric- 
tive effect  of  this  ride  on  non-mehiber  roads  is  evident.  In  competi- 
tion with  the  Terminal  Co.  was  the  Wiggins  Ferry  Co.,  which  operated 
car  transfer  boats  across  the  river  and  which  possessed  the  necessary 
rail  connections,  and  the  Merchant's  Bridge  with  its  allied  terminals, 
a  toll  bridge  which  had  been  constructed  after  the  formation  of  the 
Terminal  Co.,  and  which  was  open  to  all  roads  coming  into  St.  Louis. 
While  the  rates  of  these  companies  were  uniform,  there  was  competi- 
tion in  services  between  them,  and  new  roads  seeking  an  entrance  into 
St.  Louis  were  assured  of  terminal  connections  from  at  least  one  of 
the  three  companies.  There  was,  of  course,  some  duplication  and 
overlapping  of  facilities.  The  act  of  Congress  authorizing  the  con- 
struction of  the  Merchant's  Bridge  forbade  the  ownership  of  its  stock 
by  any  other  bridge  company  or  stockholder  therein. 

This  provision  was  later  eliminated  by  Congress  and  immediately 
thereafter  the  Terminal  Co.  acquired  stock  control  of  the  Merchant's 
Bridge  and  related  terminal  companies.  In  1892,  the  Rock  Island  at- 
tempted to  obtain  an  independent  entrance  to  the  city.  It  accordingly 
sought  to  acquire  control  of  the  stock  of  the  Wiggins  Co.  The 
Temiinal  Co.  looked  askance  at  this  project  and  a  battle  for  control 
of  the  Ferry  Co.  ensued,  its  shares  bemg  pushed  up  to  an  abnormal 
price.  The  final  result  being  m  doubt,  a  compromise  was  effected  by 
which  the  Rock  Island  was  admitted  as  a  member  of  the  Terminal  Co., 
the  shares  of  the  Ferry  Co.  which  it  had  acquired  being  turned  over  at 
cost  to  the  Terminal  Co.  Control  of  the  city's  terminal  facilities  was 
thus  concentrated  in  one  company  and  the  separate  properties  were 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  55 

thereafter  operated  as  a  single  system.  The  Government  thereupon 
brought  suit  for  dissolution  and  the  Court  held  the  combination  to  be 
illegal. 

At  the  outset,  the  Court  conceded  that  the  imification  of  the  ter- 
minal facilities  and  the  elimination  of  competition  among  them  was 
not  necessarily  an  unlawful  restraint  of  trade.  Illegality  would  de- 
pend, according  to  Mr.  Justice  Lurton,  "upon  the  intent  to  be  infeiTcd 
from  the  extent  of  the  control  thereby  secured  over  instrumentalities 
which  such  commerce  is  under  compulsion  to  use,  the  method  by  which 
such  control  has  been  brought  about  and  the  manner  in  which  that  con- 
trol has  been  exerted."  ^'^  That  the  purpose  of  the  combination  was 
to  obtain  control  of  all  the  terminals  and  to  climmate  competition  was 
made  an  express  finding  of  fact.  The  power  thus  obtained  had  not 
been  abused,  the  non-member  companies  having  been  permitted  to  use 
the  terminal  connections  at  the  same  rates  charged  the  14  member 
companies.  The  free  competition  of  the  other  roads  with  respect  to 
theu'  railroad  business  proper  had  therefore  not  been  unpeded.  The 
Terminal  Co.  had,  however,  discriminated  against  traffic  originating 
Avithin  an  area  of  100  miles  of  St.  Louis  and  had  made  certain  arbi- 
trary rebilling  charges  which  were  unfavorable  to  the  eastern  traffic. 
But  the  Court  made  it  clear  in  its  opinion  that  its  decision  did  not 
rest  upon  these  practices.  Nor  was  it  grounded  on  the  mere  fact  that 
monopoly  control  had  been  attained.  The  Court  apparently  believed 
that  unification  was  highly  expedient.  The  decision  seems  to  be  based 
upon  the  fact  that  because  of  the  peculiar  geographical  situation,  there 
was  no  possibility  of  potential  competition.  Had  it  been  feasible  to 
construct  new  facilities  or  if  membership  in  the  defendant  company 
had  been  open  to  all  roads,  the  combination  would  probably  have  been 
upheld.     Thus  it  is  stated: 

It  cannot  be  controverted  that,  in  ordinary  circumstances,  a  number  of  inde- 
pendent companies  might  combine  for  the  purpose  of  controlling  or  acquiring 
terminals  for  their  common  but  exclusive  use.  In  such  cases  other  companies 
might  be  admitted  upon  terms  or  excluded  altogether.  If  such  terms  were  too 
onerous,  there  would  ordinarily  remain  the  right  and  power  to  construct  their 
own  terminals.  But  the  situation  at  St.  Louis  is  most  extraordinary,  and  we  base 
our  conclusion  in  this  case,  in  a  large  measure,  upon  that  fact.^^ 

To  recapitulate  therefore,  we  find  the  Court  stressing  three  factors: 
(1)  the  intent  to  obtain  a  monopoly,  (2)  the  method  by  which  monopoly 
is  obtained,  and  (3)  the  manner  in  which  monopoly  control  is  exerted. 
However,  in  emphasizing  the  fact  that  non-member  roads  were  com- 
peUed  to  use  the  system  and  could  be  excluded  by  the  adverse  votes 
of  the  member  roads,  it  seemingly  takes  the  position  that  the  mere 
existence  of  the  power  of  exclusion,  although  not  exercised  is  violative 
of  the  act.  On  the  other  hand,  it  suggests  that  had  potential  com- 
petition been  physically  possible  and  economically  feasible,  the 
unification  might  not  have  been  unlawful.^^  At  no  place  in  the 
opinion  does  it  indicate  whether  it  regarded  as  wrongful  the  method 
by  which  control  was  obtained.  It  does  in  passing  state  that  "To 
close  the  door  to  competition  large  sums  were  expended  to  acquire 
stock  control."  ^'^  But  tliis  statement  can  hardly  be  regarded  as 
condemnatory  of.  the  "method"  of  combination  employed,  which,  as 

"  Id.  at  395. 

s'  Id.  at  405.    It  is  possible  to  put  a  different  interpretation  on  the  language  quoted  in  the  text,  although 
my  construction  is  supported  by  other  passages  in  the  opinion.    See,  e.  g.,  id.  at  409. 
"  Id.  at  398. 
«» Id.  at  398. 


55  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

we  have  seen,  was  a  stock  acquisition  followed  by  a  merger.  It 
stresses  the  discriminatory  practices  of  which  the  terminal  company 
was  guilty,  holding  that  they  were  not  consistent  with  freedom  of 
competition,  but  it  is  extremely  unlikely  that  the  case  would  have  been 
differently  decided  had  there  been  no  such  abusive  charges.  Unlike 
the  Standard  Oil  ^^  and  Tobacco  ^^  cases,  the  record  was  free  of  any 
evidence  of  predatory  practices  or  the  exclusion  of  competitors. 
Here  the  wrongful  purpose  was  inferred  from  the  extent  of  control 
and  the  power  of  the  combination,  whereas  in  the  Tobacco  ^^  case, 
the  Court  drew  the  inference  from  the  wrongful  practices  rather  than 
the  size  of  the  combination.  The  rates  charged  non-members  were 
not  excessive;  they  were  no  greater  than  those  imposed  upon  members; 
members  received  no  dividends  from  the  company;  and  besides  the 
terminal  systems  were  subject  to  regulation  by  the  Interstate  Com- 
merce Commission. 

The  Court's  decree  is  most  illuminating,  in  ascertaining  what  was 
the  true  basis  of  the  decision.  The  Government's  prayer  for  dissolu- 
tion was  not  granted.  Instead,  the  parties  were  given  leave  to  submit 
a  plan  for  the  reorganization  of  the  Terminal  Co.,  providing  for 
admission  to  stock  membership  of  any  existing  or  future  railroad  and 
calling  for  reasonable  rates  for  such  roads  as  did  not  desire  to  become 
joint  owners  of  the  terminal  properties.^'*  The  jurisdiction  of  the 
Interstate  Commerce  Commission  over  rates  w^as  expressly  reserved 
and  a  provision  added  that  if  the  parties  could  not  agree  on  such  a 
plan,  the  Court  would  then  enter  a  decree  of  dissolution. 

It  is  apparent  from  this  decree  that  the  Court  recognized  the 
advantages  of  unification  and  desired  to  preserve  the  resulting  efficien- 
cies without  impairing  competition  among  the  roads.  To  put  an 
end  to  the  discriminatory  charges  was  possible  without  dissolving 
the  combination.  Whether  or  not  the  three  systems  were  jointly 
operated,  additional  facilities  were  not  likely  to  be  added  and  hence 
the  Court  had  to  accept  as  its  datum  the  improbability  of  new  com- 
petition arising.  The  problem  therefore  was  to  restore  competitive 
equality  as  to  the  railroad  business  proper  by  either  destroying  the 
combination  or  by  dividing  the  monopoly  control  of  the  Terminal 
service  among  all  the  roads,  existing  or  prospective.  The  disturbance 
of  the  parity  which  had  previously  been  enjoyed  by  all  the  roads  thus 
seems  to  be  the  chief  impetus  to  judicial  intervention.  Where  the 
field  is  open  to  newcomers,  monopoly,  the  Court  seems  to  imply,  is 
not  necessarily  wrongful;  where,  however,  potential  competition  is 
obstructed  by  a  ''neck-of-the-bottle"  monopoly,  the  monopoly  must 
be  regulated  or  dissolved. "^^ 

81  (19n)  221  U.  S.  1. 

"(1911)  221  U.  S.  100. 

«3  Ibid. 

"  The  decree  also  forbade  the  discriminatory  charges  and  required  the  elimination  of  the  offensive  clauses 
in  the  membership  contract. 

"  The  execution  of  the  decree  was  involved  in  Ex  Parte  United  States,  (1913)  226  U.  S.  420.  The  decree 
was  interpreted  in  United  States  v.  Terminal  Railroad  Association  of  St.  Louis,  (1915)  236  U.  S.  194.  In  a 
petition  by  the  western  roads  to  have  the  Terminal  Association  adjudged  in  contempt  of  the  decree  because 
of  certain  allegedly  discriminatory  transfer  charges,  the  Supreme  Court  held  in  Terminal  Railroad  Asso- 
ciation V.  United  States  (1924)  266  U.  S.  17,  tliat  tlic  decree  did  not  cover  such  rates  and  therefore  there  was  no 
contempt.  In  Chicago,  Rock  Island  &  Pacific  Railwnti  Co.  v.  Baltimore  &  Ohio  Railroad  Co.,  113  I.  C.  C.  681 
(1926),  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  found  tlie  cliarges  to  be  unreasonable  and  prescribed  a  proper 
rate.  On  appeal,  it  was  held  that  tlie  Commission's  ruling  was  not  based  on  evidence  showing  the  reason- 
ableness or  unreasonableness  of  tlie  action  taken  by  the  roads.  Baltimore  cfe  Ohio  Railroad  Co.  v.  United 
States,  (1928)  277  U.  S.  291.  At  the  present  time  the  Association  is  jointly  controlled  by  15  railroad 
companies.    Moody,  Railroads  (1940)  1391. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  57 

5.    RAILROAD    CASES 

The  Union  Pacific  ^^  and  Southern  Pacific  "'  litifjations  concerned 
the  legaHty  of  the  acquisition  by  hirge  transportation  systems  of  the 
stock  in  other  carriers.  The  Union  Pacific  had  its  eastern  termini  at 
Omaha,  Neb.,  and  Kansas  City,  Mo.,  at  wliich  points  it  connected 
with  other  systems  heading  to  Chicago  and  thence  to  points  east.  Its 
main  Une  extended  from  Omaha  almost  due  west  to  Ogden,  Utali,^^ 
where  it  joined  the  Central  Pacific,  a  road  extending  from  Ogden  to 
San  Francisco.  From  Ogden,  a  branch  extended  northwest  to  Port- 
land, Ore.  A  steamship  line  was  operated  by  the  company  between 
Portland  and  San  Francisco.  Union  Pacific  thus  had  no  direct  rail 
connection  with  San  Francisco,  being  obliged  at  Ogden  either  to  use 
the  Central  Pacific  facilities  or  to  route  its  shipments  to  Portland  and 
thence  to  San  Francisco  by  water.^^  Southern  Pacific  owned  the  entire 
capital  stock  of  the  Central  Pacific  Ry.  Co.  and  operated  its  lines 
under  a  long-term  lease. '°  Its  own  tracks  extended  from  New 
Orleans  through  Texas,  New  Mexico,  Arizona,  and  California  to  Los 
Angeles  and  San  Francisco,  thence  to  Portland.  It  also  operated  a 
fleet  of  vessels  from  New  Orleans  to  New  York. 

In  1901,  the  Union  Pacific  through  its  subsidiary,  the  Oregon 
Short  Line  R.  R,  Co.,  purchased  a  46  percent  stock  interest  in 
Southern  Pacific.  The  Government  contended  that  the  stock  pur- 
chase violated  the  Sherman  Act  and  brought  suit  to  compel  the  divest- 
ment of  the  stock.  The  Court  sustained  the  contention  of  the  Govern- 
ment and  ordered  the  sale  of  the  stock. 

This  clearly  was  no  "neck-of-the-bottle"  case.  Unlike  the  Terminal 
case,''^  potential  competition,  while  unlikely  because  of  either  the  cost 
of  constructing  new  roads  or  the  difficulty  of  combining  new  systems, 
was  not  physically  impossible.  The  combmation  of  the  two  roads 
resulted  m  no  monopoly.  If  Union  Pacific  competed  with  Southern 
Pacific,  then  by  the  same  token,  both  roads  were  in  competition  with 
the  other  transcontinental  systems.  Unlike  the  Northern  Securities'^ 
case,  the  roads  were  not  parallel,  they  did  not  ply  between  the  same 
cities  and  did  not  even  have  the  same  termini.  Competition  between 
them  related  to  the  transcontinental  traffic  and  some  local  business. 
The  combination  therefore  mainly  eliminated  competition  between  one 
branch  of  the  business  of  these  gigantic  roads;  it  neither  elimmated 
competition  in  the  field  of  transcontinental  transportation  at  large, 
nor  did  it  shut  the  door  to  new  competition. 

89  United  States  v.  Union  Pacific  Railroad  Company,  (1912)  226  U.  S.  61.  The  opinion  was  written  by 
Justice  Day  for  a  court  composed  of  White,  C.  J.,  McKenna,  Holmes,  Lurton,  Hughes,  Lamar,  and  I'itney, 
JJ.    Van  Devantcr,  J.,  took  no  part  in  the  determination  of  the  case. 

67  United  States  v.  Southern  Pacific  Company,  (1922)  259  U.  S.  214.  The  opinion  was  written  by  Justice 
Day  for  a  majority  composed  of  Taft,  C.  J.,  Holmes,  Van  Devanter,  Pitney,  and  Clarke,  JJ.  McKenna,  J., 
dissented,  while  McReynolds  and  Brandeis,  JJ.,  took  no  part  in  the  decision  of  the  case. 

69  A  branch  joins  Ogden  and  Salt  Lake  City.  There  is  also  a  Union  Pacific  line  which  begins  at  the  Kan- 
sas City  terminal,  continuing  west  to  Denver,  where  it  cuts  directly  north  to  Cheyenne  on  the  main  road. 

69  By  1912,  when  the  case  was  finally  decided,  it  also  had  the  option  of  using  the  independent  Western 
Pacific  tracks  to  San  Francisco,  or  the  San  Pedro,  Los  Angeles  and  Salt  Lake  line  to  Los  Angeles.  The 
Western  Pacific  R.  R.,  opened  in  1911,  ran  between  San  Francisco  and  Salt  Lake  City  broadly  parallel  to 
Central  Pacific,  and  was  the  westerly  link  of  the  Gould  transcontinental  system,  joining  at  Salt  Lake  City 
the  Denver  &  Rio  Grande  R.  R..  which  extended  eastward  to  Denver.  See  Moody,  Railroads  (1930)  1764. 
The  San  Pedro,  connecting  Salt  Lake  City  with  Los  Angeles  was  jointly  controlled  by  Senator  Clark  and 
the  Oregon  Short  Line  R.  R.  Co.,  a  subsidiary  of  Union  Pacific.  The  road  was  permanently  established 
in  1912.     Union  Pacific  acquired  Clark's  interest  in  1921.     Id.  at  1246,  1260. 

'"  In  1885,  Central  Pacific  leased  its  properties  to  Southern  Pacific  for  99  years.  The  stock  acquisition  came 
in  1899.  The  United  States,  in  the  later  action  against  Southern  Pacific,  contended  both  transactions  were 
illegal. 

"  (1912)  224  U.  S.  383. 

"  (1904)  193  U.  S.  197. 

291144 — 41 — No.  38 5 


5g  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Moreover,  the  predatory  practices  and  the  exclusion  of  competitors 
which  characterized  the  Standard  Oil  ^^  and  Tobacco  cases  ''*  were- 
lacking  here,  as  were  the  arbitrary  charges  and  discriminations  of 
the  Terminal  case.  ^^  Nor  do  we  have  any  increases  in  rates  or  any 
monopoly  profits;  besides,  the  combined  roads  were  under  the  super- 
vision of  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission.  The  only  counter- 
part for  the  wrongful  purpose  and  intent  to  monopolize  stressed  in 
the  previous  cases  was  Harriman's  Napoleonic  ambition  to  control, 
the  important  carriers  in  the  West — an  ambition  which  had  been 
thwarted  by  Morgan  in  the  Northern  Pacific  struggle  and  by  the 
decision  of  the  Supreme  Court  in  Harriman  v.  Northern  Securities  CoJ^ 
and  which  was  certainly  difficult  if  not  impossible  of  attainment. 

Most  of  the  factors  which  were  emphasized  in  previous  cases  are 
thus  lacking.  To  say  that  the  case  rests  upon  an  intent  to  obtain 
a  monopoly  is  to  fly  in  the  face  of  the  facts.  The  most  that  can  be- 
said,  and  the  Court  went  no  further,  is  that  the  purpose  of  the  acquisi- 
tion was  to  eliminate  competition  between  the  two  systems,  but  such 
a  purpose  is  present  in  the  combination  of  any  two  competing  busi- 
nesses. Are  we  not  compelled  to  conclude  that  the  holding  of  the 
Court  is  that  the  unification  of  control  and  management  of  two  giant 
companies  doing  a  substantial  proportion  of  the  total  business  in  a 
field,  with  a  consequent  elimination  of  competition  between  them,, 
is  unlawful  notwithstanding  that  a  monopoly  is  not  attained,  and 
notwithstanding  further  that  no  predatory  methods  are  employed,, 
and  competitors  are  left  unrestrained?  The  following  excerpt  from 
the  Court's  opinion  indicates  the  scope  of  its  holding: 

The  consolidation  of  two  great  competing  systems  of  railroad  engaged  in  inter- 
state commerce  by  a  transfer  to  one  of  a  dominating  stock  interest  in  the  other 
creates  a  combination  which  restrains  interstate  commerce  within  the  meaning 
of  the  statute,  because,  in  destroying  or  greatly  abridging  the  free  operation  of 
competition  theretofore  existing,  it  tends  to  higher  rates.  United  States  v.  Joint 
Traffic  Association,  supra,  557.  It  directl.y  tends  to  less  activity  in  furnishing 
the  public  with  prompt  and  efficient  service  in  carrying  and  handling  freight  and 
carrying  passengers,  and  in  attention  to  and  prompt  adjustment  of  the  demands 
of  patrons  for  losses,  and  in  these  respects  puts  interstate  commerce  under  re- 
straint. Nor  does  it  make  any  difference  that  rates  for  the  time  being  may  not 
be  raised  and  much  money  be  spent  in  improvements  after  the  combination  is 
effected.  It  is  the  scope  of  such  combinations  and  their  power  to  suppress  or 
stifle  competition  or  create  monopoly  which  determines  the  applicability  of  the- 
act." 

Two  further  aspects  of  the  decision  should  be  noted.  It  is  the- 
existence  of  the  power  to  stifle  competition  and  not  its  exercise  which 
is  frowned  upon.  And  the  view  expressed  in  the  American  Tobacco 
case  "^  that  the  form  of  the  combination  is  not  a  material  factor  is  reiter- 
ated. Thus  in  rapid  succession  the  pool,  the  trust,  the  holding  com- 
pany, the  consolidation,  the  merger,  and  now  the  stock  acquisition,, 
were  banned.'^ 

In  the  Southern  Pacific  case,^^  the  Court  held  that  the  stock  acquisi- 
tion of  Central  Pacific  by  Southern  Pacific  violated  the  Sherman 
Act.     The  Court  stated: 

'3  (1911)  221  IT.  S.  1. 

'<  (101  n  221  U.  S.  106. 

'»  (1912)  224  U.  S.  383. 

'«  (lOOS)  197  U.  S.  244. 

"  (1912)  220  U.  S.  61,  88. 

"  (1911)  221  U.  S.  106. 

'»  The  dpcree  of  dissolution  was  more  drastic  than  that  in  the  Northern  Securities  case.  Union  Pacific  was: 
not  permitted  to  (iistribiito  Southern  Pacific  stock  to  its  shareholders  as  was  attempted.  United  States  v. 
Union  Pacific  Railroad  Company  (1913),  226  U.  S.  470. 

••  United  States  v.  Soutfiern  Pacific  Company  (1922),  259  U.  S.  214. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  59 

Such  combinations,  not  the  result  of  normal  and  natural  growtii  and  doveloji- 
mcnt,  but  sin-inging  from  the  formation  of  holding  coiupanics,  or  .stock  jnirchascs, 
resulting  in  the  unified  control  of  different  roads  or  systems,  naturally  competi- 
tive, constitute  "a  menace  to,  and  restraint  upon,  that  freedom  of  commerce 
which  Congress  intended  to  recognize  and  protect,  and  which  the  public  is  entitled 
to  have  protected."     *     *     * 

These  cases,  collectively,  establish  that  one  system  of  railroad  transportation 
cannot  acquire  another,  nor  a  substantial  and  vital  part  thereof,  when  the  effect 
of  such  acquisition  is  to  suppress  or  materially  reduce  the  free  and  normal  flow  of 
competition  in  the  channels  of  interstate  trade.*' 

The  only  basis  for  holding  tho  two  Toads  oompotitivo  is  by  regarding 
Central  Pacific  as  a  natural  link  in  the  Union  Pacific  system.  As  the 
Central  Pacific  had  been  operated  since  1885  by  Southern  Pacific 
under  a  long-term  lease,  this  assumption  seems  somewhat  gratuitous. 
But  the  Com't  even  at  the  time  of  the  Union  Pacific  case  ^^  hinted  at 
the  desirability  of  the  imification  of  the  Union  and  Central  Pacific 
lines  and  seemed  determined  to  regard  both  roads,  regardless  of  their 
separate  ownership,  as  part  of  one  transcontinental  system.  Nor 
was  there  any  danger  of  monopoly  here.  The  combined  roads  were 
subject  to  the  active  and  vigorous  competition  of  the  other  railway 
systems.  The  presence  of  such  competition  in  all  the  raihvay  cases 
should  be  carefully  noted  in  view  of  w^hat  the  Court  has  said  and  done 
in  other  cases.  Thus,  as  late  as  1922,  w^e  find  the  views  expressed  in 
the  Northern  Securities  case  ^^  still  being  followed — the  elimination  of 
competition  between  two  competing  companies  is  unlawful  notwith- 
standing that  competition  in  the  field  at  large  continues  unabated.^* 

6.    SHOE    MACHINERY    TRUST 

The  first  Shoe  Machinery  case  ^^  was  a  criminal  prosecution  of  the 
moving  spirits  of  the  United  Shoe  Machinery  combine,  which  united 
the  following  companies:  (1)  Consolidated  and  McKay  Lasting 
Machine  Co.  (controlled  by  WinslowO,  which  prior  to  1899,  the  year 
of  the  consolidation,  produced  60  percent  of  the  lasting  machines 
made  in  this  country,  (2)  the  Goodyear  Shoe  Machinery  Co.  (con- 
trolled by  How^e),  making  80  percent  of  the  welt-sewing  machines  and 
10  percent  of  the  lasting  machines,  (3)  the  McKay  Shoe  Manufac- 
turing Co.,  making  70  percent  of  all  the  heeling  machines  and  80 
percent  of  the  metallic  fastening  machines  produced  in  the  United 
States,  and  (4)  the  Eppler  Welt  Machine  Co.,  manufactmers  of 
welt-sewing  machines,  its  percentage  of  the  domestic  output  not  being 
indicated  by  the  Court.  The  indictment  charged  the  defendants 
with  violating  the  Sherman  Act  by  combining  these  companies  and 

M  Id.  at  230. 

82(1912)  226  U.  S.61. 

"  (1904)  193  U.  S.  197. 

*<  The  subsequent  proceedings  relating  to  the  ownership  of  Central  Pacific  are  interesting.  Southern 
Pacific  applied  to  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  in  1922  for  authority  under  par.  2  of  sec.  5 
of  the  Interstate  Commerce  Act  to  control  Central  Pacific  by  stock  ownership  and  lease,  and  contended  that 
the  Supreme  Court  decision  did  not  preclude  this  relief.  The  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  held  for 
the  applicant  on  February  6,  1923,  on  a  finding  that  the  arrangement  would  be  "in  tho  public  interest." 
See  76  [.  C.  C.  .508  (1923).  In  United  States  v.  Southern  Pacific  Co.  (D.  Utah  1923),  290  Fed.  443,  the  court 
sustained  the  order  of  the  Commission.  No  further  court  proceedings  were  had.  Commissioner  McMan- 
amy  in  his  opinion  on  the  final  consolidation  plan,  159  I.  C.  C.  522,  573  (1929)  said: 

"It  has  been  demonstrated  that  the  extraordinary  and  comprehensive  power  which  renders  inoperative 
certain  State  and  Federal  laws  is  sufficient  to  enable  this  Commission  in  effect  to  annul  a  decision  of  tho 
Supreme  Court  of  the  United  States.     Control  of  Central  Pacific  by  Southern  Pacific,  76  I.  C.  C.  508." 

In  the  final  consolidation  plan,  the  Commission  places  the  .'Southern  Pacific  Co.  (159  I.  C.  C.  at  541)  and 
its  subsidiaries,  including  Central  Pacific  (id.  at  523)  in  system  No.  16. 

85  United  States  v.  Winslow  (1913),  227  U.  S.  202.  Mr.  Justice  Holmes  wrote  the  opinion,  supported  by  a 
unanimous  Court  composed  of  White,  C.  J.,  McKenna,  Day,  Lurton,  Hughes,  Van  Devanter,  Lamar,  and 
Pitney,  JJ.    This  was  the  same  court  that  had  decided  the  Terminal  and  Union  Pacific  cases. 


go  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

by  imposing  onerous  terms  in  the  leases  imder  which  the  machines 
which  they  manufactm^ed  were  rented  to  shoe  manufacturers.  The 
district  court  construed  the  indictment  as  questioning  the  vahdity  of 
a  consoHdation  of  noncompeting  companies  and  as  being  confined  to 
the  issue  of  the  consoHdation  alone,  apart  from  the  tying  leases.  It 
therefore  sustained  the  defendants'  demurrers.  The  only  question 
before  the  Supreme  Court  on  the  appeal  was  whether  the  combination, 
standing  by  itself,  violated  the  Sherman  law.^^  The  opinion  of  the 
Court,  by  Mr.  Justice  Holmes,  was  as  follows: 

On  the  face  of  it  the  combination  was  simply  an  effort  after  greater  efficiency. 
The  business  of  the  several  groups  that  combined,  as  it  existed  before  the  combi- 
nation, is  assumed  to  have  been  legal.  The  machines  are  patented,  making  them 
is  a  monopoly  in  any  case;  the  exclusion  of  competitors  from  the  use  of  them  is 
of  the  very  essence  of  the  right  conferred  by  the  patents,  Paper  Bag  Patent  case, 
210  U.  S.  405,  429,  and  it  may  be  assumed  that  the  success  of  the  several  groups 
was  due  to  their  patents  having  been  the  best.  As,  hy  the  interpretation  of  the 
indictment  below,  195  Fed.  Rep.  591,  and  hy  the  admission  in  argument  before  us, 
they  did  not  compete  with  one  another,  it  is  hard  to  see  why  the  collective  business 
should  be  any  worse  than  its  component  parts.  It  is  said  that  from  70  to  80 
percent  of  all  the  shoe  machinery  business  was  put  into  a  single  hand.  This 
is  inaccurate,  since  the  machines  in  question  are  not  alleged  to  be  types  of 
all  the  machines  used  in  making  shoes,  and  since  the  defendants'  share  in  com- 
merce among  the  States  does  not  appear.  But  taking  it  as  true  we  can  see  no 
greater  objection  to  one  corporation  manufacturing  70  percent  of  three  non- 
competing  groups  of  patented  machines  collectively  used  for  making  a  single 
product  than  to  three  corporations  making  the  same  proportion  of  one  group  each. 
The  disintegration  aimed  at  by  the  statute  does  not  extend  to  reducing  all  manu- 
facture to  isolated  units  of  the  lowest  degree.  It  is  as  lawful  for  one  corporation 
to  make  every  part  of  a  steam  engine  and  to  put  the  machine  together  as  it  would 
be  for  one  to  make  the  boilers  and  another  to  make  the  wheels.  Until  the  one 
intent  is  nearer  accomplishment  than  it  is  by  such  a  juxtaposition  alone,  no  intent 
could  raise  the  conduct  to  the  dignity  of  an  attempt.^' 

The  Court  accepted,  and  in  fact  regarded  itself  bound  by  the  lower 
court's  interpretation  of  the  indictment.  The  indictment  explicitly 
states  that  the  purpose  of  the  combination  was  to  suppress  competition 
and  the  facts  as  alleged  showed  that  there  was  some  overlapping  of  the 
business  of  these  companies.  Goodyear's  lasting  machines  in  view 
of  the  company's  strength  and  dominance  in  allied  lines  could  effec- 
tively compete  with  Consolidated's  machines.  Adding  Goodyear's 
10  percent  to  Consolidated's  60  percent  was  not  a  matter  to  be  thus 
lightly  disposed  of  and  cannot  be  regarded  as  a  case  of  de  minimis. 
The  same  is  true  of  the  combined  control  of  the  welt-sewing  machines 
put  out  by  Goodyear  and  Eppler.  Because  this  industry  was  charac- 
terized by  patent  monopolies  was  no  reason  to  permit  the  further 
concentration  of  production  in  the  hands  of  one  company;  if  anything 
the  scrutiny  should  have  been  more  searching. 

But  even  assuming  that  the  companies  were  noncompetitive,  does  it 
follow  that  the  Sherman  Act  permits  a  union  of  complementary  com- 
panies where  each  of  the  constituent  units  possesses  substantial  con- 
trol of  its  own  line?  ^^  May  not  such  integration  stand  on  a  separate 
footing  from  that  of  companies  all  of  which  are  subject  to  competition 
in  their  own  field?  Where  four  giant  companies  control  successive 
stages  in  the  production  of  the  final  commodity,  though  they  are  not 

w  This  i.s  a  paraphrase  of  the  statement  made  by  Justice  Holmes  in  the  Supreme  Court  opinion.  Id.  at 
210.  Acluiilly,  the  lower  court  regarded  the  charge  with  respect  to  the  tying  clauses  as  stating  a  separate 
ofT'n<^e  -Mid  sustained  the  count  in  the  indictment  relating  thereto.  SeeUnited  States  v. Winslow  (D.  Mass. 
1912).  195  Ked.  .^78,  594. 

«'  Unit'd  stairs  v.  Winslow  (1913),  227  U.  S.  202,  217.    [Text  italics  ours.] 

"See  Stone,  J.,  dissenting  in  Federal  Trade  Commission  v.  Eastman  Kodak  (1927),  274  U.  S.  619,  629. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


61 


n  actual  competition,  there  is  some  likelihood  of  competition  arising 
miong  them.  The  maniifactiir(>r  of  welt-sewing  machines  m  i.y  desire 
.o  expand  into  allied  fields.  Such  potential  competition  is  not  without 
ninatory  value  in  keeping  prices  at  a  reasonable  level;  provided,  of 
lourse,  there  is  no  restrictive  agreement  among  such  manufacturers. 
3ut  with  all  the  companies  combined,  the  newcomer  is  without  Icvcr- 
ige  to  break  into  the  field  and  must  invent  an  entire  line  of  shoe 
nachinery  ratlier  than  one  or  two  new  machines.  The  patent  situa- 
ion  plus  the  consolidation  created  a  wall  against  new  competition, 
jomparable  to  that  resulting  from  the  physical  conditions  stressed  in 
he  St.  Louis  Terminal  case.^^ 

Contemporaneously  with  the  criminal  prosecution,  the  Government 
lad  filed  a  bill  in  equity  for  the  dissolution  of  the  United  Shoe  Ma- 
chinery Co.,  proceedings  in  which  the  technicalities  of  criminal  pro- 
lediu-e  did  not  preclude  a  full  consideration  of  the  entire  history  of 
liis  combination,  and  a  careful  weighing  of  all  the  operative  facts, 
rhe  facts  were  most  complicated  and  were  largely  in  dispute — patient 
examination  of  the  testimony  was  necessary  to  evaluate  the  rival  con- 
entions  and  to  resolve  the  conflicting  versions  of  the  facts.  The 
5upreme  Court,  however,  rested  its  opinion  on  the  findings  of  the 
ower  court,  contained  in  tlu'ee  separate  opinions.^°  The  trial  court 
lad  held  that  the  companies  combined  in  the  original  consolidation 
vere  not  competitive,  and  that  the  56  subsequent  acquisitions  were 
either  of  companies  operating  under  noncompetitive  patents  or  were 
nade  to  compose  actual  or  threatened  patent  litigation.  The  Supreme 
I'ourt  did  not  review  the  conflicting  evidence;  ^*  it  merely  analyzed  a 
'ew  of  the  acquisitions,  to  show  that  the  lower  court's  conclusions 
vere  supported  by  the  weight  of  the  evidence. 

The  production  of  the  United  Co.  has  been  estimated  at  about  90-95 
percent  of  the  shoe  machinery  used  in  this  country.^^  Giving  the 
'ullest  weight  to  the  contentions  of  the  defendants,  and  assuming 
vith  the  Court  that  the  properties  and  patents  thus  put  together  were 
essentially  complementary  to  each  other,  the  fact  remains  that  there 
lad  been  some  competition  among  them  and  that  the  consolidation 
completely  eliminated  this  competition.     The  situation  is  undoubtedly 

88  (1912)  224  U.  S.383. 

w  United  States  v.  United  Shoe  Machinery  Company  (D.  Mass.  1915),  222  Fed.  349. 

M  United  States  v.  United  Shoe  Machinery  Company  (1918),  247  U.  S.  32.  Mr.  Justice  McKenna  wrote  the 
ipinion  for  the  majority,  consisting  of  White,  C.  J.,  Holmes  and  Van  Devanter,  JJ.,  deciding  that  both  the 
!ombination  and  the  tying  clauses  were  lawful;  Mr.  Justice  Day  dissented,  holding  the  tying  clauses  to  he 
mlawful  restraints  of  trade.  Mr.  Justice  Clarke  dissented  on  the  ground  that  the  defendant  was  a  monop- 
)ly.  Note  his  views  on  the  significance  of  the  form  of  the  combination.  Id.,  at  77.  Mr.  Justice  Pitney 
;oncurred  in  both  dissents,  and  each  writer  concurred  in  the  other  dissent.  Brandeis  and  McReynolds,  JJ., 
lid  not  take  part  in  the  consideration  of  the  case. 

M  This  chart  is  taken  from  the  dissenting  opinion  of  Mr.  Justice  Clarke,  id.  at  89: 


'Machines  in  use  in  this  country 


Lasting  machines 

Standard  screw  machines-- 

Pegging  machines 

Tacking  machines 

Welt  sewing  machines 

Outsole  stitching  machines 

Loose-nailing  machines 

Heeling  machines 


Manufac- 

Manufac- 

tured by 

tured  by 

defendants 

all  others 

7,496 

7 

409 

None 

146 

None 

3,488 

6 

2,527 

142 

2,676 

758 

1,835 

24 

2,019 

y," 

In  UnUed  Shoe  Machinery  Co.  v.  La  Chapelle,  212  Mass.  467,  99  N.  E.  289,  the  Court  assumes  that  the 
ompany  controlled  90-95  percent  of  the  industry  at  the  time  of  suit. 


(]2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

complicated  by  the  presence  of  multifarious  patents. ^^  Wliile  some  of 
these  patents  mutually  infringed  each  other,  some  were  probably 
valid,  and  were  competitive  in  the  sense  that  they  were  capable  of 
performing  the  same  functions.  That  the  combination  shut  the  door 
to  potential  competition  cannot  be  seriously  questioned.  Reference 
has  already  been  made  to  the  concentration  of  patents  for  allied 
machinery;  what  was  equally  as  important  was  the  congestion  or 
"blocking"  resulting  from  the  various  acquisitions  of  patents  and 
inventions  covering  the  entire  field,  which  made  it  almost  impossible 
to  invent  a  machine  which  would  not  conflict  in  some  part  with  one  of 
the  combination's  patents.  The  inventive  genius  of  the  sellers  of  the 
patents  was  generally  mortgaged  to  the  company  in  the  form  of  cove- 
nants not  to  compete  and  covenants  to  smrender  their  future  inven- 
tions to  the  company.^*  In  this  way  the  important  technological 
knowledge  and  skill  without  which  new  competition  could  not  possibly 
arise  were  put  beyond  the  reach  of  new  capital.  And  finally  there 
were  the  famous  tying  agreements  under  which  the  lessees  of  the 
machinery  were  forbidden  from  using  machines  of  any  other  company 
either  for  the  process  for  which  United's  machines  had  been  leased 
or  in  connection  with  any  of  the  other  processes  or  stages  incident  to 
the  manufacture  of  shoes.  The  potency  of  this  device,  regardless  of 
its  legality ,^^  in  keeping  out  new  competition  can  scarcely  be  ignored. 
The  intent  to  dominate  the  industry  was  fairly  to  be  inferred  from  the 
long  series  of  acquisitions  and  the  tying  agreements.^^ 

To  repeat  then,  there  was  here  monopoly  power  both  to  fix  prices 
and  to  exclude  new  competition.  Irrespective  of  whether  there  was 
any  real  competition  in  the  industry  at  an  earlier  date,  there  assuredly 
was  none  at  the  time  of  suit.  The  combination  took  the  form  of 
consolidation  and  holding  company;  the  acquisitions  sometimes  were 
of  assets,  sometimes  of  stock;  the  consideration  was  cash  or  stock. 

The  Court  throughout  its  opinion  stresses  the  efficiency  of  the 
combination,  but  it  furnishes  the  reader  with  little  evidence  of  the 
basis  for  its  conclusion.    It  states — 

The  company,  indeed,  has  magnitude,  but  it  is  at  once  the  result  and  cause  of 
efficiency,  and  the  charge  that  it  has  been  oppressively  used  is  not  sustained. 
Patrons  are  given  the  benefits  of  the  improvements  made  by  the  company  and 
new  machines  are  substituted  for  the  old  ones  without  disproportionate  charge. ^^ 

'■'  As  to  the  patents,  the  Court  said:  "No  one  can  tell  the  strength  of  the  competition  that  may  be  in  a 
patent.  It  may  be  more  than  competition:  it  may  be  destruction,  and  the  Antitrust  Act  surely  docs  not 
require  the  acceptance  of  that  or  forbid  etTort  to  prevent  it.  But  even  if  such  extreme  does  not  impend, 
certainly  improvement  of  business  and  its  efficiency  can  be  striven  for  without  offense  to  the  law."  247 
U.  S.  32,  53. 

To  the  effect  that  the  combination  of  competing  patents  may  violate  the  Sherman  law,  see  (1924)  24  Col. 
L.  Rev.  654. 

«<  In  United  Shoe  Machinery  Co.  v.  La  Chapelle,  212  Mass.  4G7,  99  N.  E.  289,  the  company  asked  specific 
performance  of  a  contract  by  which  the  defendant-inventor  agreed  to  assign  all  patents  which  he  might  take 
out  while  in  I'jlaintilT's  employ,  and  for  10  years  thereafter.  The  defendant  had  refused  to  assign  after  his 
discharge,  and  set  up  the  defense  tliat  plaintiff  was  a  monopoly  in  violation  of  the  Sherman  Act.  The 
Court  held  for  the  defendant,  stressing  that  a  corporation  with  90-95  percent  of  the  industry  is  a  monopoly 
even  though  its  control  is  derived  from  the  ownership  of  patents. 

«s  The  Supremo  Court  held  the  leases  to  be  lawful  under  the  Sherman  Act.  After  the  enactment  in  1914 
of  the  Clayton  Act,  the  restrictions  in  the  leases  were  held  to  be  illegal  under  section  3  of  that  act.  United 
Shoe  Muchinery  Corporation  v.  United  States  (1922),  258  U.  S.  451. 

'«  The  Court's  coiUrary  finding  on  the  issue  of  intent  is  difficult  to  understand.  The  motives  of  the  pro- 
ponents of  the  comt)inali(>n  need  not  be  iiniiugued;  it  may  be  that  they  were  desirous  of  composing  serious 
patent  difficulties:  it  may  l>e  that  their  chief  aim  was  to  increase  the  etTiciency  of  the  combining  units;  but 
it  seems  equally  clear  that  they  intended  to  dominate  the  industry  and  to  narrow  the  field  of  actual  and 
potential  competition  to  the  vanishing  jioint.  See  the  oi>iiiion.  247  II.  S.  32,  54.  There  was  evidence  that 
Winslow  had  threatened  competitors  with  extinction,  and  while  the  Court  passes  over  such  threats  as  being 
"isolated  instances,  separated  in  time,  without  relation,  not  coordinated  acts  in  a  scheme  of  oppression," 
their  probative  value  on  the  issue  of  intent  was  not  entirely  inconsequential.    Id.  at  55. 

"  Id.  at  56. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER  (33 

The  leasing  of  machinery  was  highly  beneficial  to  the  small  shoe 
/manufacturer  who  lacked  the  capital  for  an  out  and  out  purchase. 
The  only  oppression  of  which  the  United  was  guilty  was  the  tying 
leases.  But  is  there  any  evidence  that  as  a  result  of  the  combination, 
costs  of  manufacturing  machinery  were  lowerccl,  rental  chaigcs  de- 
creased, the  position  of  labor  improved,  or  technological  advance 
furthered?    On  these  points  the  opinion  is  not  very  explicit.^* 

7.    STEEL  CORPORATION 

The  United  States  Steel  Corporation  escaped  dissolution  by  a 
margin  of  one  judicial  vote.  Only  seven  justices  participated  in  the 
decision,  and  the  Court  divided  four  to  three. ^^  The  Steel  Corporation 
was  organized  as  a  holding  company  in  1901  to  acquire  the  stock  ui 
12  operating  companies  in  exchange  for  its  own  stock.  The  events 
leading  up  to  its  formation  and  the  intricate  financial  details  of  its 
organization  are  not  pertinent  to  the  present  discussion.  The  Steel 
Corporation  originally  issued  securities  amounting  to  $1,402,846,817, 
of  which  $508,227,394  was  in  common  stock.  It  has  generally  been 
believed  that  the  entire  common  stock  was  watered.  The  promoters' 
profits  were  stupendous,  being  estimated  at  $62,500,000.  Every 
stage  in  the  production  of  iron  and  steel  from  the  mining  of  ore  and  the 
manufacture  of  coke  to  the  production  of  pig  iron,  as  well  as  the  manu- 
facture of  rails,  bars,  plates,  sheets,  tubes,  rods,  and  other  finished 
products,  came  under  the  control  of  the  holding  company.  The 
lower  court  estimated  the  percentage  of  control  of  steel  products  to  be 
between  80  and  90  percent;  this  figure  seems  much  too  high,  most 
wi'iters  placing  it  at  about  60  or  70  percent.  At  the  time  of  suit,  this 
had  been  reduced  to  about  50  percent.  One  of  the  purposes  of  the 
combination,  as  found  by  the  Supreme  Court,  was  the  monopolization 
of  the  steel  industry.  However,  a  complete  monopoly  in  the  sense  of 
the  entire  elimination  of  competition  was  never  attained.  At  the 
outset,  and  increasingly  as  the  years  went  by,  the  corporation  was 
subjected  to  the  competition  of  independents  for  part  of  the  domestic 
business,  and  as  indicated,  the  company  did  not  retain  its  proportion- 
ate share,  although  its  gross  business  increased  tremendously.  Price 
competition  was  avoided  by  pooling  agreements,  and  in  later  years,  by 
tacit  understandings  reached  at  the  famous  Gary  dinners.  The  policy 
of  the  company  was  not  to  eliminate  the  independents;  it  engaged  in 
none  of  the  brutal  practices  that  characterized  the  earlier  trusts;  it 
followed  a  "live  and  let  live"  policy,  keeping  the  independents  in 
check  by  agreement. 

The  fact  that  the  combination  was  efi^ected  through  the  formation 
of  a  holding  company  was  given  no  weight  by  the  Court.  The  fact 
that  the  purpose  of  the  combination  was  the  monopolization  of  the 

8'  Before  leaving  the  case,  mention  should  be  made  of  the  Court's  fear  that  the  drastic  remedy  of  dissolu- 
tion demanded  by  the  Government  would  disrupt  the  entire  industry  and  prejudice  the  interests  of  invest- 
tors.  It  apparently  felt  that  the  difficulties  of  effecting  a  dissolution  were  insuperable.  The  scries  of  ques- 
tions which  it  poses  and  the  psycological  bias  which  it  reveals  may  explain  the  iuefTectiveness  of  many  of  the 
dissolution  decrees  which  have  been  handed  down  by  the  courts.  The  Court  further  felt  that  the  Govern- 
ment's delay  of  12  years  in  bringing  suit  condoned  "the  offense  if  oHense  there  was."  Id.  at  45.  Compare 
the  Southern  Pacific  cant  on  the  effect  of  dPlay. 

"  United  States  v.  United  States  Steel  Corporation  (1920).  251  U.  S.  417.  The  majority  opinion  was  written 
by  Mr.  Justice  McKenna— White,  C.  J.,  Holmes,  and  Van  Devanter,  JJ.,  concurring.  Mr.  Jastice  Day 
wrote  a  dissenting  opinion  with  which  Pitney  and  Clarke,  JJ.,  concurred.  McReynolds  and  Brandeis, 
JJ.,  took  no  part  in  the  decision  of  the  case. 


g4  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

industry  was  condoned  because  the  purpose  had  failed  of  achievement. 
The  tremendous  overcapitalization  and  excessive  promoters'  profits 
passed  without  the  slightest  disapproval.  The  fact  that  the  vast 
power  which  was  concentrated  in  the  holding  company  had  not  been 
abused  was  strongly  emphasized  and  probably  saved  the  company 
from  dissolution.  This  was  not  the  first  instance  of  the  integration  of 
both  competing  and  noncompeting  companies  to  be  presented  to  the 
Court,  for  in  both  the  Oil  ^  and  Tobacco  -  cases  the  combination  had 
branched  out  into  allied  and  complementary  lines,  and  in  the  Northern 
Securities  ^  and  Union  Pacific  *  cases,  the  combining  companies  com- 
peted as  to  part  of  their  business  only.  In  their  respective  spheres, 
the  Carnegie  and  Federal  Steel  Corporations,  two  of  the  constituent 
companies,  were  no  less  important  and  no  less  in  competition  with  each 
other  than  were  the  Northern  Pacific,  Great  Northern,  Union  Pacific, 
and  Southern  Pacific  Railroads  with  respect  to  the  transcontinental 
traffic.  While  the  Court  talks  of  the  efficiencies  resulting  from  the 
steel  combination  and  the  benefits  which  the  public  had  derived 
therefrom,^  there  was  no  evidence  that  similar  economies  might  not 
have  been  effected  by  the  railroad  combinations.  In  the  railroad  cases, 
however,  the  Court  had  been  most  unsympathetic  to  the  attempts  of 
counsel  to  justify  the  combinations  on  that  ground. 

Ordinarily,  the  proof  of  a  wrongful  intent  and  of  actual  violations 
of  a  criminal  statute  would  tend  to  strengthen  the  Government's 
case;  here  it  seemed  to  have  the  contrary  effect.  The  Court  appeared 
to  be  much  impressed  by  the  fact  that  the  combination,  having 
failed  to  eliminate  competition  at  an  early  period  of  its  history,  saw 
the  error  of  its  ways  and  voluntarily  abandoned  its  original  purpose 
of  monopoly.  To  be  sure,  the  corporation,  in  the  course  of  years, 
had  bought  up  some  additional  companies  but  only  under  circum- 
stances found  by  the  Court  to  be  extenuating,  and  as  to  one  purchase, 
only  after  the  approval  of  President  Theodore  Roosevelt  had  first 
been  obtained.  And  the  fact  that  the  corporation  had  found  it 
necessary  to  enter  price-fixing  arrangements  with  its  competitors 
and  otherwise  violate  the  Sherman  law  with  their  assistance  was 
deemed  conclusive  proof  of  its  impotency  and  lack  of  monopolistic 
power. 

Mere  size  by  itself,  the  Court  felt,  was  not  conclusive  since  "the 
law  does  not  make  mere  size  an  offense,  or  the  existence  of  unexerted 
power  an  offense.  It,  we  repeat,  requires  overt  acts  and  trusts  to  its 
prohibition  of  them  and  its  power  to  repress  or  punish  them.  It  does 
not  compel  competition  nor  require  all  that  is  possible."  ^  That  is 
to  say,  it  is  the  exercise  of  monopoly  power  and  not  its  possession 
which  is  determinative.  Having  thus  stated  the  issue,  the  next 
question  is  what  constitutes  an  improper  exercise  of  monopoly  power. 

'  (1011)  221  XI.  S.  1. 

2  (Mtll)  221  U.  S.  10f>. 

3  (1904)  193  U.  S.  197. 
M1912)  226U.  S.  61. 

»  "In  conclusion  we  are  unable  to  see  that  the  public  interests  will  be  served  by  yielding  to  the  contention 
of  the  Government  respecting  the  dissolution  of  the  company  or  the  separation  from  it  of  some  of  its 
subsidiaries;  and  wc  do  see  in  a  conl  rary  cnnchision  a  risk  of  injury  to  the  public  interest,  including  a  material 
disturbance  of,  and,  it  may  be  si'iious  detriment  to,  the  foreign  trade.  And  in  submission  to  the  policy  of 
the  law  and  its  fortifying  proliihiiions  the  public  interest  is  of  paramount  regard."  United  States  v.  United 
States  Steel  Corporation,  supra,  at  4.")7. 

6  "The  coriHiratiun  is  uiKioubtcdly  of  impressive  size  and  it  takes  an  effort  of  resolution  not  to  be  affected 
by  it  or  to  exaggcralr  its  inllutMuv."    (1920)  251  U.  S.  417,  451. 

The  Qovornnical's  contention  that  "a  combination  may  he  illegal  because  of  its  purpose;  it  may  be  illegal 
because  it  acquires  a  dominating  power,  not  as  a  result  of  normal  growth  and  development,  but  as  a  result 
of  a  combination  of  competitors"  was  explicitly  rejected.    Id.  at  447. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  g5 

To  the  Court,  this  means  the  unilateral  fixing  of  a  monopoly  price 
and  the  exclusion  of  competitors — and  the  corporation  was  found 
guilty  of  neither. 

The  Court  approached  the  case  from  an  additional  angle.  If 
there  was  competition  in  the  industry  after  the  merger,  the  com- 
bination could  have  no  monopoly.  The  officers  of  the  corporation, 
its  competitors,  and  200  customers  all  testified  that  competition  was 
genuine,  direct,  and  vigorous.  The  Court  was  impressed  by  the 
fact  that  "no  competitor  came  forward  and  said  he  had  to  accept  the 
Steel  Corporation's  prices."  ^  There  being  competition,  the  (;on- 
clusion  was  irresistible  that  there  was  no  monopoly.  Therefore, 
whether  the  test  of  legality  under  the  statute  be  monopoly  power  or 
its  exercise,  the  defendant  had  not  violated  its  provisions. 

The  Steel  Corporation  controlled  a  smaller  percentage  of  the  indus- 
try than  any  other  ''trust"  that  had  been  prosecuted  up  to  the  time  of 
this  decision,  with  the  possible  exception  of  the  Union  Pacific-Southern 
Pacific  combination.  There  were  in  the  industry  several  independents 
capable  of  vigorous  competition.  The  Court  did  not  seem  averse  to 
forbidding  the  previous  restraints  on  this  competition,  but  the  Gov- 
ernment had  not  sought  such  relief,  presumably  because  the  restraints 
had  been  abandoned. 

Eliminating  the  factors  of  wrongful  motive  and  the  participation 
by  the  corporation  in  the  violation  of  the  statute  by  the  price-fixing 
arrangements  with  competitors,  as  the  Court  did,  there  was  nothing 
left  to  the  case  but  the  element  of  size.  Does  the  Sherman  law  forbid 
the  formation  of  a  capital  combination  controlling  50  percent  of  an 
industry,  which  no  longer  intends  to  monopolize  the  field  and  which 
does  not  restrain  or  limit  the  competition  of  its  rivals?  The  Court 
felt  that  this  was  the  sole  issue  before  it  and  the  only  issue  it  sought 
to  determine.*  Following  this  decision,  the  Government  dismissed 
its  appeals  in  other  cases,  then  pending  before  the  Court,  from 
similar  lower  court  rulings.^ 

'  Id.  at  447.  The  Government  had  relied  upon  the  movement  of  prices,  but  this  the  Court  regarded  as 
insufficient  in  view  of  the  explicit  testimony  of  the  200  customers  that  no  "adventitious  interference  was 
employed  to  fix  or  maintain  prices  and  that  they  were  constant  or  varied  according  to  natural  conditions." 
Id.  at  449.  When  the  Government  pointed  out  that  there  were  some  40,000  customers  of  which  only  200 
had  been  called,  the  Court  responded  that  200  was  a  representative  number  and  pointed  out  that  the  Govern- 
ment had  not  seen  fit  to  call  the  others  itself. 

'  As  in  the  Shoe  Machinery  case,  the  Court  was  impressed  by  the  difficulties  of  dissolution  and  the  possible 
injury  to  investors.  Id.  at  453.  The  fact  that  the  Government  had  stood  by  for  10  years  before  instituting 
proceedings  was  not  without  influence  upon  the  decision.  Id.  at  453.  The  case,  it  will  be  remembered,  was 
argued  in  March  1917,  just  before  war  was  declared,  and  reargued  in  the  latter  part  of  1919  before  the  Nation 
had  acclimated  itself  to  the  new  peace. 

The  Court  was  satisfied  that  the  price-fixing  arrangements,  which  were  stopped  several  months  before  the 
suit  was  started,  were  not  abandoned  in  anticipation  of  the  suit,  but  from  a  conviction  of  their  futility. 
Id.  at  445.  The  only  cases  reviewed  by  the  Court  were  the  Standard  Oil  and  Tobacco  decisions,  and  they  were 
distinguished  on  the  ground  of  wrongful  purpose  and  predatory  practices.    Id.  at  455. 

Mr.  Justice  Day  in  his  dissent,  while  agreeing  that  mere  size  by  itself,  if  the  product  of  natural  growth  is 
not  condemned  by  the  law,  emphatically  expressed  his  view  that  combination  is  not  a  method  of  natural 
growth,  and  that  the  size  and  power  thus  obtained  are  unlawful.  lie  pointed  out  that  in  both  the  Standard 
Oil  and  Tobacco  cases  the  corporations  dissolved  had  been  long  in  existence  at  the  time  of  the  (lovernment's 
suit,  but  that  had  not  deterred  the  court  from  decreeing  dissolution.  A  dominating  corporation,  con- 
trolling one-half  of  the  country's  steel  business,  resulting  from  a  combination  of  competing  companies,  in  his 
opinion  violated  the  act,  and  he  voted  for  a  dissolution  to  restore  competitive  conditions. 

•  United  States  v.  Keystone  Watch  Case  Co.  (E.  D.  Pa.  1915),  218  Fed.  502,  appeal  dismissed  on  motion  of 
the  United  States  (1921),  257  U.  S.  664  (42-47  percent  of  the  industrv);  United  States  v.  American  Can  Com- 
pany (D.  Md.  1916),  230  Fed.  859.  decree  denying  dissolution  entered  in  (D.  Md.  191(1),  2.34  Fed.  1019,  appeal 
dismissed  on  motion  of  the  United  States  (1921),  256  U.  S.  706  (50  percent):  United  Slates  v.  Quaker  Oats 
Companu  (N.  D.  111.  1916),  232  Fed.  499,  appeal  dismissed  on  motion  of  the  United  States  (1920),  253  U.  S. 
499  (70-75  percent). 


QQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

8.    ANTHRACITE  COAL  CASES 

The  Beading  Anthracite  Coal  case  ^°  was  decided  within  7  weeks  of 
the  Steel  "  decision.  A  full  Court  sat  and  the  majority  opinion  was; 
delivered  by  Mr.  Justice  Clarke,  one  of  the  dissenters  in  the  Steel  case. 
Three  of  the  four  members  of  the  Steel  case  majority  dissented,  but  it  is 
noteworthy  that  Mr.  Justice  McKenna  joined  the  majority. ^^ 

Practically  all  the  anthracite  coal  in  the  country  is  found  in  three 
fields  in  northeastern  Pennsylvania,  the  most  northerly,  the  Wyoming 
field,  with  approximately  176  square  miles  of  coal  land,  the  middle  or 
Lehigh  field  with  about  45  square  mUes,  and  the  southerly  or  Schuyl- 
kill field  with  some  263  square  miles.  The  chief  marketing  centers 
for  anthracite  are  New  York  City,  about  140  miles  by  rail  from  the 
fields,  and  Philadelphia,  about  90  miles  distant.  The  Wyoming  field 
has  six  rail  outlets  to  the  New  York  Harbor,  the  Lehigh  three,  and 
the  Schuylkill  only  two.^^  Six  of  the  carriers  either  directly  or  through 
subsidiaries  produce  about  75  percent  of  the  annual  output,  and  own 
or  control  about  90  percent  of  the  unmined  deposits. ^^ 

The  Philadelphia  &  Reading  Railroad  extends  into  the  Schuylkill 
field.  From  an  early  date,  it  began  to  acquire  coal  properties  in  this 
region  to  assure  itself  of  the  valuable  coal  traffic.  Its  holdings  were 
increased  from  70,000  acres  in  1871  to  102,573  acres  in  1891,  consti- 
tuting at  that  time  about  one-third  of  the  total  area  of  coal  lands  of 
the  State,  about  two-thirds  of  the  acreage  of  the  Schuylkill  field,  and 
about  50  percent  of  the  State's  unmined  deposits.  In  1892,  it  leased 
the  lines  of  two  important  competing  roads,  the  Central  of  New 
Jersey  and  the  Lehigh  Valley,  both  of  which  controlled  valuable  coal 
properties.  The  Central  lease  was  assailed  in  the  New  Jersey  courts, 
and  as  a  result  of  the  litigation  both  leases  were  abandoned. ^^  After 
a  receivership  in  1896,  the  company  was  reorganized  and  its  various 
properties  allocated  as  follows:  The  coal  lands  to  the  Reading  Coal  & 
Iron  Co.,  the  railroad  to  the  Reading  Railway  Co.,  and  the  equipment 
and  rolling  stock  to  the  Reading  Co.  In  all  other  respects,  the  Reading 
Co.  became  a  holding  company,  controlling  the  capital  stock  of  the 
other  two  Reading  companies.  The  formation  of  this  holding  com- 
pany was  held  in  and  of  itself  to  be  a  violation  of  the  Sherman  Act, 
the  Court  declaring: 

i"  United  States  v.  Beading  Company  (1920),  253  U.  S.  26.    The  opinion  in  the  Steel  case  was  handed  down 
on  March  1,  1920,  the  Reading  case  on  April  26,  1920.    For  the  decree,  see  (D.  C.  Pa.  1921)  273  Fed.  848,  854. 
"  (1920)  251  U.  S.  417. 

12  'I'he  majority  consisted  of  Clarke,  McKenna,  Day.  Pitney,  McReynolds,  and  Brandcis,  JJ.,  the  minor- 
ity of  White,  O.  J.,  Holmes  and  Van  Devanter,  JJ. 

"  This  is  stated  by  the  court,  id.  at  p.  42,  but  the  facts  are  somewhat  differently  stated  by  the  district 
court.     (R.  D.  Pa.  1915)  226  Fed.  229,  234. 

n  The  followiofr  table  of  the  various  percentages  of  unmined  anthracite  is  contained  in  United  States  v. 
Heading  Company  (1912),  226  U.  S.  324,  339. 

Percent 

Reading  Co _ 44.00 

LohiRh  Valley  Co 16.87 

Delaware,  I/aelcawanna  &  Western  Co... 6. 55 

Central  R.  R.  of  N.  J 19.00 

Eric  R.  R 2.59 

New  York,  Susquehanna  &  Western  R.  R .54 

Total 89.55 

The  balance  is  owned  by  independents  who  mine  about  20  percent  of  the  annual  output.  The  mines  of 
the  various  coal  companies  are  in  the  main  in  the  vicinity  of  the  tracks  of  the  parent  railroads.  Except  for 
the  Delaware,  Lackawanna  &  Western  Co.,  the  coal  properties  are  owned  by  subsidiary  operating  com- 
panies. 

i»  Stockton  V.  Central  Railroad  Compnuy  of  iXnr  Jersey.  50  N.  J.  Eq.  52,  24  Atl.  964  (1892).  The  chancelor 
held  that  the  Central  U.  It.  lc;i,';i'  to  ilic  Keadinfi  system  was  contrary  to  a  New  Jersey  statute  of  1885  for- 
biddinc  the  lease  of  a  domcstif  railroad  to  a  foreign  corporation  without  legislative  consent,  and  held  also, 
that  the  leases  tended  to  monopoly  and  hence  were  injurious  to  the  public  interest. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  (57 

Thus,  this  scheme  of  reorganization,  adopted  and  executed  G  years  after  the 
enactment  of  the  Antitrust  Act,  combined  and  dehvcred  into  the  complete  control 
of  the  board  of  directors  of  the  Holding  Company  all  of  the  property  of  much  the 
largest  single  coal  company  operating  in  the  Schuylkill  anthracite  field,  and  almost 
1,000  miles  of  railway  over  which  its  coal  must  find  its  access  to  interstate  markets. 
This  board  of  directors,  obviouslj',  thus  acquired  power:  to  increase  or  decrease 
the  output  of  coal  from  very  extensive  mines,  the  suj^ply  of  it  in  the  market,  and 
the  cost  of  it  to  the  consumer;  to  increase  or  lower  the  charge  for  transjjorting  such 
coal  to  market;  and  to  regulate  car  supply  and  other  shipping  conveniences,  and 
thereby  to  help  or  hinder  the  operations  of  independent  miners  aiid  shipjjers  of 
coal.  This  constituted  a  combination  to  unduly  restrain  interstate  commerce 
within  the  meaning  of  the  act." 

As  evidence  of  the  purpose  of  the  Reading-  combination  to  dominate 
the  Schuylkill  field  and  tlie  transportation  facilities  from  that  rco;ion 
to  the  eastern  markets,  the  Court  relied  upon  the  series  of  acquisitions 
already  described  and  the  abuse  of  the  power  which  thus  became  vested 
in  the  holding:  company.  Such  abuses  were  the  combination  of  the 
Reading  with  five  other  carriers  to  prevent  the  construction  by  the 
independent  coal  operators  of  a  new  road  to  the  eastern  seaports  and 
the  successful  suppression  of  such  contemplated  competition,  and  also 
its  participation  in  a  combination  of  carriers  and  controlled  coal  com- 
panies, \\hereby  the  present  and  future  output  of  the  independents 
was  obtained  under  exclusive  contracts  at  a  vmiform  rate  of  65  percent 
of  the  seaport  price. '^  The  participation  in  these  combinations  was 
characterized  by  the  Court  as  a  flagrant  violation  of  the  antitrust 
law. 

The  holding  company  had  also  acquired  a  controlling  stock  interest 
in  the  Central  Railroad  of  New  Jersey,  which  operated  a  road  from 
the  Wyoming  and  Lehigh  regions  to  the  New  York  harbor,  and  which 
owned  eleven-twelfths  of  the  stock  of  the  Lehigh  &  Wilkes-Barre  Coal 
Co.,  a  coal  company  with  extensive  properties  in  the  Wyoming  field 
amounting  to  about  19  percent  of  the  total  unmined  deposits  in  the 
State. '^  The  Court  found  that  both  the  railroad  and  its  coal  com.pany 
were  in  direct  competition  with  the  system  of  the  acquiring  company. 
Reading  and  Central  railroads  together  carried  an  anthracite  tonnage 
of  18,000,000  tons  or  about  one-third  of  the  total  domestic  produc- 
tion.^^ "This  acquisition",  said  the  Court,  "placed  the  Holding  Com- 
pany in  a  position  of  dominating  control  not  only  over  two  great  com- 
peting interstate  railroad  carriers  but  also  over  two  great  competing 
coal  companies,  engaged  extensively  in  mining  and  selling  anthracite 
coal,  wdiicli  must  be  transported  to  interstate  markets  over  the  con- 
trolled interstate  lines  of  railway."  As  "this  dominating  power  was 
not  obtained  by  normal  expansion  to  meet  the  demands  of  a  business 
growing  as  a  result  of  superior  and  enterprising  management,  but  by 
deliberate,  calculated  purchase  for  control",  the  Court  held  the  com- 

>6  United  States  v.  Reading  Company  (1920'),  253  U.  S.  26,  47. 

1'  Both  acts  of  the  combination  were  held  unlawful  in  a  former  suit,  United  States  v.  Reading  Company 
(1912),  226  U.  S.  324.  As  this  case  is  concerned  with  a  loose-knit  combination,  it  is  not  analyzed  in  this 
section.  However,  one  aspect  of  the  case  should  be  noted.  The  competing  roads  formed  a  company  to 
acquire  the  stock  of  an  independent  producer,  which  was  the  largest  supporter  of  the  projected  railroad, 
each  of  the  defendant  railroads  acquiring  a  stock  interest  in  the  new  company.  The  unified  control  of  the 
company  bv  the  6  competitors  was  held  unlawful.  Cf.  State  ex  inf.  Barber  v.  Armovr  Packing  Company, 
265  Mo.  12l",  176  S.  W.  382  (1915),  in  which  the  court  held  a  company  with  7  percent  of  the  meat  packing 
trade  of  the  United  States  to  be  illegal  where  its  owners  were  the  leading  meat  packers  of  the  covmtry. 

IS  Of  the  total  coal  mined  in  1912,  Wilkes-Barre  produced  7!^2  percent  and  Reading  Coal  16  percent.  United 
States  V.  Reading  Co.  (E.  D.  Pa.  1915)  226  Fed.  229,  249.  This  latter  court  estimated  Central's  unmined 
deposits  at  10  percent  and  not  19  percent,  the  figure  given  by  the  Supreme  Court  in  the  first  Reading  case. 

19  United  States  v.  Reading  Company  (1920),  253  U.  S.  26,  53.  It  is  clear  that  their  production  of  coal  did  not 
exceed  this  figure  of  their  coal  transportation.  In  1912  the  combined  production  of  their  coal  companies 
amounted  to  only  231.2  percent  of  the  annual  output.  The  percentage  of  unmined  deposits  was,  as  we  have 
seen,  much  higher. 


gg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

bination  unlawful,  stating  "that  such  a  power,  so  obtained,  regardless 
of  the  use  made  of  it,  constitutes  a  menace  to  and  an  undue  restraint 
upon  interstate  commerce  within  the  meaning  of  the  Antitrust  Act."^° 
As  authority  for  its  position  the  Court  cited  with  approval  and 
quoted  statements  in  the  Northern  Securities  ^'  and  the  Union  Pacific  ^^ 
cases  that  it  is  the  existence  of  power  and  not  its  exercise  which  deter- 
mines whether  the  act  has  been  violated.  The  Court  also  quoted 
from  a  previous  case  to  the  effect  that  the  good  results  of  the  combina- 
tion or  the  good  intentions  of  its  prime  movers  constitute  no  defense 
for  a  violation  of  the  statute. ^^  It  was  further  held  that  the  joint 
control  of  carrier  and  coal  company  violated  the  commodities  clause 
of  the  Hepburn  Act.^*  A  decree  of  dissolution  was  accordingly 
entered,  the  constituent  companies  being  freed  from  the  domination 
of  the  holding  company,  and  their  separate  independence  reestab- 
lished. A  more  drastic  dissolution  had  not  up  to  that  time  been 
ordered  by  the  Court. ^^ 

Here,  then,  we  have  a  combination  with  about  33 K  percent  of  the 
annual  production  of  anthracite  coal  declared  unlawful  under  the  anti- 
trust laws.  Is  the  result  to  be  placed  on  the  ground  that  the  defend- 
ants joined  a  combination  of  other  carriers  to  exclude  competition  and 
to  monopolize  the  entire  output  of  coal?  These  violations  had  oc- 
curred long  prior  to  this  suit  and  had  been  enjoined  in  a  separate  pro- 
ce  -ding  more  than  8  years  before  the  decision  of  this  case  by  the  Su- 
preme Court.  The  Court  emphatically  states  that  the  formation  it- 
self of  the  Reading  holding  company  rather  than  the  abusive  exercise 
of  its  power  violated  the  antitrust  laws.  Apart  from  the  acts  enjoined 
in  the  previous  suit,  the  combination  had  been  guilty  of  no  predatory 
practices.  The  case  cannot  be  rested  on  the  ground  that  the  com- 
modities clause  of  the  Hepburn  Act  was  violated.  The  Hepburn  Act 
had  no  application  to  the  Central  of  New  Jersey  acquisition;  it  per- 
tained merely  to  the  joint  control  of  carrier  and  coal  company.  The 
Court,  moreover,  regarded  the  combination  as  violating  the  antitrust 
laws,  and  did  not  rest  its  decision  upon  the  Hepburn  Act.     Nor  can  the 

"  Id.  at  57. 

21  (1904)  193  U.  S.  197. 

22(1912)  226  U.  S.  61. 

23  International  Harvester  Co.  v.  Missouri  (1914),  234  U.  S.  199,  209.  "It  is  too  late  in  the  day  to  assert 
against  statutes  which  forbid  combinations  of  competing  companies  that  a  particular  combination  was  in- 
duced by  pood  intentions  and  has  had  some  good  eiTect." 

2«  34  Stat.  5S1  (li.'OCO,  49  II.  S.  C.  A.,  sec.  1,  par.  8  (1920).  This  act  declares  that  it  shall  be  unlawful  for 
any  railroad  company  to  transport  in  interstate  commerce  "any  article  or  commodity,  *  *  *  mined, 
or  produced  by  it,  or  under  its  authority,  or  which  it  may  own  in  whole  or  in  part,  or  in  which  it  may  have 
any  interest,  direct  or  indirect,  *  *  *."  In  United  States  v.  Delaware  &  Hudson  Company  (1909),  213 
U.  S.  3(j(),  it  was  held  that  the  act  is  not  necessarily  violated  by  the  transportation  of  coal  shipped  by  a  com- 
pany in  which  the  railroad  has  a  stock  interest.  Where,  however,  the  railroad  owns  all  the  stock  of  the  coal 
company,  dcpriviii!;  it  of  all  real  iixlependent  existence  and  making  it  virtually  an  agency  of  the  carrier, 
the  transportation  of  its  coal  is  unlawful.  United  States  v.  Leiiigl}  ^'alley  Railroad  Co.  (1911),  220  U.  S.  257. 
The  te.st  is  wliether  there  is  a  bona  fide  separate  administration  of  the  affairs  of  the  coal  company.  The 
next  device  adopted  by  the  coal-carrier  combinations  to  circumvent  the  statute  was  outlawed  in  United 
States  V.  Dehurare,  Lnckairannn  &  Western  Railroad  Co.  (1915),  238  U.  S.  510.  The  Delaware,  Lackawanna 
&  Western  Uailroad  (^i.  incorporated  the  Delaware,  Lackawanna  &  Western  (^oal  Co.,  selling  the  stock 
of  the  cn\\  co!iii)aiiy  to  the  stocktiolclcrs  of  the  railroad.  The  coal  company  agreed  to  buy  all  the  coal  mined 
by  the  railroad  and  not  to  handle  tlic  output  of  any  other  company.  The  Court  held  the  contract  unlawful. 
Stating  that  the  arrangement  made  the  coal  company  merely  an  instrumentality  of  the  carrier.  The  Read- 
ing and  LeluL'h  set-ups,  which  were  obvious  modifications  of  the  arrangements  described  above,  are  dis- 
cussed in  the  text.  See  (19151  14  Mich.  L.  Rev.  49:  (19201  19  id.  221:  (19211  19  id.  5.53:  (19.32)  41  Yale  L.  J. 
439.  In  United  States  v.  Flgin,  J.  &  E.  Ry.  Co.  (1936),  298  U.  S.  492,  the  Court  held  that  the  commodities 
clause  of  the  Interstate  Commerce  Act  had  not  been  violated  by  the  ownership  of  all  the  stock  of  the  Elgin, 
J.  it  K.  Ity.  Co.,  by  the  Cnited  States  Steel  Corporatiim,  a  holding  company,  notwithstanding  the  fact  that 
60  percent  of  the  t  onnage  carri('(l  by  the  railroad  consisted  of  commodities  shipped  by  subsidiaries  of  the  steel 
corporation.  The  Court  stressed  the  absence  of  interlocking  directorates,  "the  infrequent  partici- 
pation by  the  hokling  comiiany  in  the  allairs  of  the  railroad,  the  separate  accounting  systems  of  each  com- 
pany, and  the  independent  ownership  by  each  of  their  re.spective  facilities  and  stated  the  mere  existence  of 
power  to  exercise  an  active  control,  without  its  exercise,  docs  not  constitute  a  violation  of  the  law.  See  the 
sharp  di.ssent  of  Mr.  .lustice  Stone,  id.,  at  504. 

"  For  subsequent  litigation  over  the  decree,  see  Continental  Insurance  Company  v.  United  States,  Read- 
ing Covipany  (1922),  259  U.  S.  156. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  69 

decision  be  put  on  the  ground  that  a  monopoly  was  acquired  or  sought. 
There  was  no  evidence  that  the  Reading  Co.  planned  to  buy  up  all 
or  a  dominant  part  of  the  competing  coal  companies  and  carriers; 
such  wrongful  mtent  as  there  may  have  been  was  clearly  ineffectual. 
No  one  will  pretend  that  an  active  and  vigorous  competition  pre- 
vailed in  the  anthracite  fields,  but  the  absence  of  competition  was 
to  be  accounted  for  by  the  collusive  agi-eements  among  the  operating 
companies  and  carriers  and  not  by  the  Reading  combination.  While 
large  capital  was  required  to  embark  upon  the  industry,  the  artificial 
restrictions  on  potential  competition  had  at  least  been  removed  by 
the  decree  in  the  first  Reading  case.  The  conclusion  is  inescapable- 
that  the  union  of  the  Reading  and  the  Central  interests  did  not 
stifle  competition  in  the  industry  at  large ;  at  best  it  merely  eliminated 
competition  between  two  of  the  largest  factors.  Does  not  the  case 
liold  that  a  combmation  of  giant  companies  doing  a  substantial  part 
of  the  business  in  their  fields  is  unlawful? 

United  States  v.  Lehigh  Valley  Railroad  Co}^  dealt  with  another 
series  of  acquisitions  in  this  industry.  The  Lehigh  Valley  Railroad 
extends  to  the  Wyoming  and  Lehigh  fields,  reaching  but  one  colliery 
in  the  Schuylkill  region.  Much  the  larger  part  of  its  tonnage  is 
derived  from  the  Wyoming  field  and  it  transports  more  coal  than 
any  other  railroad  in  the  country.  Like  the  other  coal  carriers,  it 
has  extensive  coal  holdings  in  territories  tributary  to  its  lines.  Most 
of  its  purchases  preceded  the  enactment  of  the  Sherman  law,  but  from 
1900  to  1905,  it  made  several  important  stock  acquisitions  in  competing 
coal  companies,  culminating  in  the  purchase  of  the  entire  capital  stock 
of  Coxe  Bros.  &  Co.  in  1905  for  $17,440,000  in  cash.  This  company 
was  the  largest  independent  coal  operator  on  the  Lehigh  Valley  lines, 
and  controlled  not  only  extensive  coal  deposits  but  also  all  the  capital 
stock  of  the  Delaware,  Susquehanna  &  Schuylkill  Raihoad,  a  50-mile 
railway  serving  many  of  the  large  independents  and  connecting  w^th 
the  Reading,  Pennsylvania,  and  Central  Railroads.  After  the  acquis'- 
tion,  the  Delaware  fell  into  disuse.  The  coal  properties  of  the  Lehigh 
were  held  by  its  controlled  company,  the  Lehigh  Valley  Coal  Co. 
The  combined  acreage  of  the  Lehigh  and  the  Coxe  companies  was 
90,719  acres,  of  which  about  two-thirds  were  located  along  the  lines 
of  the  railroad.  The  coal  companies  and  railroad  had  common 
officers,  no  dividends  were  paid  by  the  coal  companies,  the  financial 
relations  of  the  various  companies  being  "intimate  and  interlaced."" 
In  1912,  to  avoid  the  possible  application  of  the  Sherman  and  Hep- 
burn Acts,  a  subsidiary  sales  company  was  organized  to  market  the 
coal  produced.  This  device  was  a  patent  subterfuge  and  was  so 
regarded  by  the  Court. ^^  The  purpose  of  these  purchases  of  coal 
properties,  the  Court  found,  was  to  suppress  competition,  and  their 

29  (1920)  254  U.  S.  255.  Cf.  United  States  v.  Lake  Shore  and  Michigan  Southern  Railway  Co.  (S.  D.  Ohio 
1912),  203  Fed.  295. 

2'  254  U.  S.  255,  263. 

28  Id.  at  267.  The  history  of  the  company  is  a  long  record  of  attempts  to  frustrate  the  State  and  Federal 
statutes  regulating  carriers  or  business  competition.  Its  efforts  to  lease  its  lines  to  the  Reading,  as  indi- 
cated in  the  text,  proved  abortive.  It  participated  in  the  illegal  conibinntion  which  was  castigated  in  the 
first  Reading  case.  In  1911,  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  held  it  guilty  of  monopolizing  the  coal 
field  served  by  it  and  of  unjust  discrimination.  Meeker  v.  Lehigh  Valley  Railroad  Company,  21  I.  C.  C.  129, 
154,  163  (1911),  supplemental  report,  23  I.  C.  C.  480  (1912);  Meeker  v.  Lehigh  Vallty  Railroad.  (1915)  236  U.  S. 
412.  In  1915.  its  rates  were  branded  a.s  unreasonable,  and  it  was  held  guilty  of  unlawful  rebates.  In  the 
Matter  of  Rates,  etc..  Governing  the  Transportation  of  Anthracite  Coal,  35  I.  C.  C.  220  (191.5).  .\s  stated 
by  the  court,  "This  history  of  almost  25  years  casts  an  illuminating  light  upon  the  intent  and  purpose  with 
which  the  combination  here  assailed  was  formed  and  continued."  United  States  v.  Lehigh  Valley  Rail- 
road Co.,  supra,  at  269.    See  (1932)  41  Yale  L.  J.  439. 


^Q  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

ultimate  result  was  the  attainment  of  "a  practical  monopoly"  in 
"the  transportation  and  sale  of  anthracite  coal  derived  from  such 
lands."  '^     The  Court  said: 

The  area  of  the  anthracite  territory  is  so  restricted  that  to  thus  obtain  control 
of  the  supply  of  such  coal  on  a  great  system  of  railway  (the  amount  transported 
exceeded  one-fifth  of  the  entire  production  of  the  country  for  the  year  before  this 
suit  was  commenced)  by  a  combination  of  corporations,  such  as  we  have  here,  and 
by  such  methods  as  we  have  seen  were  employed,  effected  a  restraint  of  trade  or 
commerce  among  the  several  States  and  constituted  an  attempt  to  monopolize 
and  an  actual  monopolization  of  a  part  of  such  trade  or  commerce  in  anthracite 
coal,  clearly  within  the  meaning  of  the  first  and  second  sections  of  the  Antitrust 
Act  as  they  have  frequently  been  interpreted  by  this  court.^" 

The  combination  between  carrier  and  coal  companies  was  ordered 
dissolved,  the  independence  of  each  affiliated  unit  to  be  completely 
restored. ^^ 

Wliile  the  Court  talks  of  a  practical  monopoly  and  of  attempts  to 
monopolize,  it  does  not  reveal  Lehigh's  share  of  the  annual  output  of 
coal.  It  is  clear  from  the  other  coal  cases  that  the  percentage  did 
not  exceed  20  percent.  Lehigh  had  no  monopoly  in  any  real  sense 
other  than  the  regional  monopoly  which  every  carrier  possesses. 
There  were  many  other  transportation  and  coal  companies,  and  with 
Reading  and  Central  separated,  at  least  two  with  larger  unmined 
coal  holdings.^^ 

In  the  discussion  of  the  Anthracite  cases,  the  combination  of  com- 
peting coal  companies  rather  than  the  integration  of  coal  company 
and  carrier  has  been  stressed.  The  Court,  as  indicated,  declared 
both  types  of  combination  unlawful  under  the  Sherman  as  well  as  the 
Hepburn  Acts.  It  is  noteworthy  that  in  both  cases  the  stock  in  the 
coal  companies  was  acquired  either  by  the  carrier  or  a  holding  com- 
pany and  not  by  a  coal  company.  In  the  Reading  case,'^^  the  holding 
company  accpiired  Central  of  New  Jersey  stock  and  thus  obtained 
control  of  Central's  subsidiary  coal  company.  In  the  Lehigh  case,^'^ 
the  raih'oad  purchased  the  stock  in  Coxe  Co.  The  decree  of  dis- 
solution required  the  separation  of  railroad  and  coal  company,  the 
Reading  Co.  being  compelled  to  relinquish  its  holdings  of  Reading 
Railroad,  Reading  Coal  Co.,  and  Central  of  New  Jersey,  which  in 
turn  had  to  divest  itself  of  its  coal  holdings.  Lehigh  Railroad  was 
ordered  to  relinquish  control  of  its  subsidiary  coal  company  and  to 
dispose  of  its  stock  in  the  Coxe  colliery.  Under  the  decree,  a  hori- 
zontal union  of  the  Reading  and  Central  Coal  companies,  or  of  the 
two  carriers,  or  of  Lehigh  Coal  and  Coxe  Coal  companies,  was  not 
directly  forbidden.  If  there  is  difficulty  in  reconciling  these  cases 
with  the  Steel  decision,^^  treating  them  as  involvmg  merely  combina- 

2«  Id.  at  270. 

30  Ibid. 

31  The  opinion  was  written  by  Clarke,  J.,  for  a  court  composed  of  McKenna,  Day,  Van  Devanter,  and 
Pitney,  JJ.  Cliief  Justice  White  and  Mr.  Justice  Holmes  concurred  specially,  stating  that  they  regarded 
themselves  bound  by  the  previous  determinations  in  the  Reading  and  Lackaxcanna  case's.  McReynolds 
and  Brandeis,  JJ.,  did  not  sit. 

The  court  ordered  the  dissolution  of  the  intercorporate  relations  between  the  Lehigh  Valley  Railroad 
Co.,  the  LehiKli  N'alley  Coal  Co.,  Coxe  Bros.  &  Co.,  Inc.,  the  Delaware,  Susquehanna  <*L'  Schuylkill  Rail- 
road Co.,  and  I  lie  Lehigh  Valley  (^oal  Sales  Co.  with  such  disiiosition  of  all  sec'urities  as  woulii  establish 
their  entire  indeiiendence.  The  contract  between  the  coal  company  and  sales  company  was  declared  void, 
and  the  sales  company  was  freed  from  the  domination  of  the  railroad,  and  was  in  ellect,  as  well  as  in  form, 
to  be  an  independent  dealer  in  coal,  free  to  comi>ele  with  the  coal  or  railroad  companies. 

32  The  Reading  Co.  with  44  percent  and  the  Central  Railroad  of  New  Jersey  with  19  percent  while  the 
Lehigh  Valley  Co.  had  but  16.87  percent. 

33  (1912)  22G  U.S.  324. 
31  (1920)  254  U.  S.  255. 
3»  (1920)  251  U.  S.  417. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER  'J  I 

ttions  of  coal  companies,  how  explain  the  decisions  under  the  Sherman 
Act  if  they  are  treated  as  vertical  integrations  only? 

The  percentage  of  control  in  both  Anthracite  cases  was  less  than 
that  in  the  Steel  case.^^  The  form  of  combination,  at  least  in  the 
Reading  case,^'^  was  identical.  The  combinations  cooperated  with  the 
independents — in  one  case  to  fix  prices,  in  the  others  to  drive  out  com- 
petitors. Cooperation  with  competitors  in  all  the  cases  had  tlieoret- 
ically  ceased  at  the  time  of  suit,  in  one  voluntarily,  and  in  the  others 
under  compulsion  of  law.  The  intent  to  monopolize  had  been  aban- 
doned— or  at  least  had  proven  ineffectual — in  all  three  cases.  Monop- 
oly power  was  not  attained  by  any  of  the  defendants.  Apart  from 
combining  with  competitors,  no  defendant  was  guilty  of  predatory 
practices,  although  to  be  sure  the  anthi-acite  companies  had  joined 
with  their  competitors  to  drive  out  new  competition,  whereas  Steel 
had  been  content  with  price-fixing.  The  likelihood  of  potential  com- 
petition was  about  the  same ;  perhaps  more  likely  in  the  steel  industry. 
All  the  corporations  were  preeminent  in  their  respective  fields,  but 
there  was  a  fair  number  of  strong  independents.  The  majority  opin- 
ion in  the  Anthracite  cases  bears  an  uncommonly  strong  resemblance 
to  the  dissenting  opinion  in  the  Steel  case}^  The  Steel  decision  is 
neither  cited  nor  discussed  by  Mr.  Justice  Clarke. 

9.  ANACONDA  MERGER 

Somewhat  reminiscent  of  the  Steel  case  ^^  is  the  decision  in  Geddes 
V.  Anaconda  Copper  Mining  Co}^  This  was  a  bill  by  minority  stock- 
holders of  the  Alice  Gold  and  Silver  Mining  Co.  to  have  a  deed  of  the 
corporation's  property  to  the  Anaconda  Copper  Co.  declared  invalid 
on  the  ground  that  the  transfer  violated  the  antitrust  laws.  The 
assets  of  the  Alice  Co.  were  sold  to  Anaconda  in  consideration  of  30,000 
shares  of  the  latter's  stock.  Anaconda  at  this  time  was  an  operating 
company  and  held  the  fee  to  the  properties  of  several  companies  which 
it  had  previously  absorbed.  The  Amalgamated  Copper  Co.,  a  holding 
company  formed  in  1899  to  serve,  as  its  name  indicated,  as  an  in- 
strumentality for  combining  the  copper  companies  in  the  country, 
controlled  the  Anaconda  Co.  by  stock  ownership.  The  promoters 
back  in  1899  had  probably  intended  to  unify  the  entire  inclustry  but 
their  efforts  proved  ineffectual,  and  in  1911  when  the  present  bill 
was  filed,  less  than  22  percent  of  the  American  output  was  produced 
by  Anaconda  and  its  associated  companies.  The  Alice  was  a  small 
copper  company.  Its  proportionate  output  is  not  indicated  by  the 
Court,  but  it  could  not  have  been  very  high  in  view  of  the  considera- 
tion given  for  it.  At  the  time  of  the  transfer,  Alice  was  in  financial 
difficulties  and  was  unable  to  operate  its  properties  profitably.  While 
the  case  goes  off  on  other  grounds,  the  Court  was  clear  that  the  pur- 
chase did  not  violate  the  Sherman  law,  the  small  proportion  of  the 
industry  not  giving  Anaconda  any  monopolistic  power. 

Much  was  made  of  the  wrongful  purpose  of  the  original  combina- 
tion, but  as  in  the  Steel  case,'^^  the  Court  felt  that  the  abandonment, 

38  md. 

3'  (1912)  226  U.  S.  324. 
38  (1920)  251  U.  S.  417. 
3«  Md. 

«i  (1921)  254  U.  S.  590.    The  opinion  was  written  by  Mr.  Justice  Clarke  for  a  court  composed  of  White 
C.  J.,  McKenna,  Holmes,  Day,  Van  Devanter,  Pitney,  and  Brandeis,  JJ.    Mr.  Justice  McRejmolds 
'Concurred  in  result. 
«'  (1920)  251  U.  S.  417. 


72  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

long  prior  to  suit,  of  the  intent  to  monopolize,  as  well  as  its  ineffective- 
ness, precluded  dissolution  under  the  Sherman  Act.  While  the  Court 
does  not  directly  pass  upon  the  earlier  acquisitions,  its  approval  of  the 
present  purchase  is  an  oblique  ruling,  at  the  very  least,  upon  the  legal- 
ity of  a  merger  not  exceeding  22  percent  of  the  mdustry,  achieved 
without  predatory  practices  or  injury  to  competitors. 

10.    INTERNATIONAL    HARVESTER    CONSOLIDATION 

The  International  Harvester  case  *^  arose  in  a  peculiar  way.  In  1902, 
5  of  the  largest  companies  manufacturing  harvesting  machinery  and 
agricultural  implements  were  consolidated  into  the  International 
Harvester  Co..  Subsequently  the  stock  of  the  only  remaining  large 
company  was  acquired. ^^  The  aggregate  output  of  the  combined 
companies  exceeded  85  percent  of  the  total  domestic  production. 
Thereafter,  the  properties  of  other  competitors  were  acquired,  steel 
and  coal  companies  were  purchased,  and  Harvester  added  other  classes 
of  agricultural  implements  to  its  lines.  The  company  was  conserva- 
tively financed,  its  stock  was  singularly  free  of  water,  the  properties 
purchased  were  not  overvalued,  and  promoters'  profits  were  unusually 
slight.  While  the  company  had  been  variously  charged  with  unfair 
practices,  it  was  guilty  of  none  of  the  brutal  methods  of  the  oil  and 
tobacco  companies  and  the  trial  court  explicitly  found  that  its 
competitors  had  not  been  unfairly  or  unjustly  treated."**  The  intent 
to  monopolize  was  inferable  from  the  size  and  power  of  the  combina- 
tion. At  the  suit  of  the  Government,  the  combination  was  ordered 
dissolved  in  1914,  the  decree  providing  for  the  division  of  the  assets 
and  business  of  Harvester  into  "at  least  3  substantially  equal,  separate, 
distinct,  and  independent  corporations  with  wholly  separate  owners 
and  stockholders."  "  Later  that  year,  the  decree  was  modified, 
pursuant  to  a  stipulation  between  the  Attorney-General  and  the  com- 
pany, eliminating  the  requirement  of  separation  into  3  companies, 
and  providing  that  the  business  and  assets  "be  divided  in  such  manner 
and  into  such  number  of  parts  of  separate  and  distinct  ownershiji  as 
may  be  necessary  to  restore  competitive  conditions  and  bring  about  a 
now  situation  in  harmony  with  law."  Harvester  then  appealed  to  the 
Supreme  Court,  but  by  agreement  of  the  parties  the  appeal  was  dis- 
missed and  a  consent  decree  was  entered  in  1918  whereunder  Harvester 
was  ordered  to  sell  3  of  its  branded  harvester  lines,  with  the  manu- 
facturing plants,  and  was  limited  to  a  single  sales  representative  or 
distributor  in  any  one  town  or  city.  Jurisdiction  to  modify  the  decree 
was  retained  in  the  event  it  failed  to  achieve  its  purpose  of  bringing 
about  "a  situation  in  harmony  with  the  law."  "^^  Relying  upon  a  study 
of  competitive  conditions  in  the  industry  made  by  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission,  the  Government  in  1918  petitioned  for  the  separation  of 
International  Harvester  into  3  companies  in  accordance  with  the 
terms  of  the  original  decree.     The  trial  court  denied  the  petition  on 

"(1927)274  U.  S.6G3. 

«Th(>  companies  consolidated  were  the  McCormick  Harvesting  Machine  Co.,  Warder,  Biishnell  & 
Qlessncr  Co.,  i:)oprinp:  Harvp-stcr  Co.,  Milwaukee  Harvester  Co.,  and  the  Plana  Manufacturing  Co.  Shortly 
after,  1).  M.  Osborne  &  Co.  was  acquired. 

"  United  St'ites  v.  International  Ilnrccster  Company  (D.  Minn.  1914),  214  Fed.  987,  993. 

<5  United  States  v.  International  Harvester  Company  (D.  Minn.  1014),  214  Fed.  987,  appeal  dismissed  on 
motion  of  appellants,  (1918)  248  U.  S.  587,  supplemental  bill,  (1927)  274  U.  S.  693.  See  (1915)  63  U.  of  Pa. 
L.  Rev.  315;  (1914)  14  Col.  L.  Rev.  659;  (1914)  28  Uarv.  L.  Rev.  87;  Eldridge,  "A  New  Interpretation  of  the 
Sherman  .\ct,"  (1914)  13  Mich.  L.  Rev.  1,  113. 

<6  The  company  thereafter  disposed  of  two  of  its  lines,  but  it  was  unable  to  find  a  purchaser  for  the  plants. 
The  third  line  was  not  sold  until  after  the  Government  brought  the  present  proceedings  for  additional 
relief  under  the  decree. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  73 

the  ground  that  the  consent  decree  had  restored  competitive  condi- 
tions, that  the  defendant's  percentage  of  control  had  been  reduced 
from  85  in  1902  to  64  in  1918,  that  the  independents  were  powerful 
enough  to  engage  in  vigorous  competition  with  Harvester,  that  de- 
fendant had  no  control  over  prices,  and  that,  in  fact,  prices  had  been 
lowered.  The  Supreme  Court  in  affirming  held  that  competitive 
conditions  had  been  restored."  The  Government's  reliance  upon  the 
contrary  conclusions  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  was  criticized 
as  follows: 

*  *  *  the  Government  relies  in  large  measure  upon  various  statements  and 
tabulations  contained  in  the  report  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  which  was 
introduced  in  evidence  over  the  objection  of  the  International  Co.  But  it  is 
entirely  plain  that  to  treat  the  statements  in  this  report — based  upon  an  ex  parte 
investigation  and  formulated  in  the  manner  hereinabove  set  forth — as  constituting 
in  themselves  substantive  evidence  upon  the  questions  of  fact  here  involved, 
violates  the  fundamental  rules  of  evidence  entitling  the  parties  to  a  trial  of  issues 
of  fact,  not  upon  hearsay,  but  upon  the  testimony  of  persons  having  first  hand 
knowledge  of  the  facts,  who  are  produced  as  witnesses  and  are  subject  to  the  test 
of  cross-examination.'"* 

One  of  the  ways  in  which  defendant  had  restricted  competition  had 
been  by  tying  up  all  the  responsible  dealers  in  a  locality  with  exclusive 
contracts  whereby  each  was  limited  to  one  of  defendant's  lines. 
Under  the  decree,  the  Court  pointed  out,  these  channels  of  trade  were 
opened  to  Harvester's  competitors.  The  Court  was  impressed  by  the 
testimony  of  the  purchasers  of  the  three  lines  sold  pursuant  to  the 
decree,  who  expressed  confidence  in  their  ability  to  compete  energeti- 
cally and  successfully  once  the  agricultural  depression  ended.  The 
Com't  further  found  that  Harvester  had  not  used  its  capital  and 
resources  to  restrain  or  suppress  competition,  that  it  had  not  controlled 
prices,  and  that  it  had  not  sold  its  machines  below  cost  except  in 
disposing  of  surplus  stock.  It  pointed  out  that  the  company's 
percentage  of  control  had  decreased  to  64  percent.  Repeating  the 
dictum  of  the  Steel  case,'^^  it  said: 

The  law,  however,  does  not  make  the  mere  size  of  a  corporation,  however 
impressive,  or  the  existence  of  unexerted  power  on  its  part,  an  offense,  when 
unaccompanied  by  unlawful  conduct  in  the  exercise  of  its  power.^o 

With  respect  to  the  company's  price  leadership,  it  said: 

And  the  fact  that  competitors  may  see  proper,  in  the  exercise  of  their  own  judg- 
ment, to  follow  the  prices  of  another  manufacturer,  does  not  establish  any  sup- 
pression of  competition  or  show  any  sinister  domination." 

Its  conclusion  from  the  evidence  was  that  International  Harvester 
had  not  only  complied  with  the  decree  but  that  a  "situation  in  har- 
mony with  the  law"  has  been  brought  about. 

All  that  the  Court  was  called  upon  to  determine  in  the  Harvester  " 
case  was  whether  the  defendant  had  complied  with  the  consent  decree 
of  1918.  The  position  might  be  taken  that  the  legality  of  a  combina- 
tion with  64  percent  control  of  an  industry  was  not  really  before  it, 
that  while  it  might  well  have  rendered  a  more  drastic  decree  were  the 

<'  United  States  v.  International  Harvester  Co.,  (1927)  274  U.  S.  693.  Mr.  Justice  Sanford  wrote  the  opinion 
for  a  Court  composed  of  Taft,  C.  J.,  Holmes,  Van  Devanter,  Sutherland,  and  Butler,  JJ.  McReynolds, 
Brandeis,  and  Stone,  JJ..  took  no  part  in  the  case. 

«  Id.  at  703. 

No  mention  was  made  of  sec.  6  (c)  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act  empowering  the  Commission 
to  make  such  investigations,  nor  account  taken  of  the  fact  that  one  of  the  purposes  of  Congress  in  creating  the 
Commission  was  to  devise  a  new  technique  for  the  eflective  formulation  of  dissolution  decrees.  See  38  Stat. 
717,  sec.  6  (c)  (1911),  15  U.  S.  C.  A.,  sec.  46  (c)  (1926). 

"  (1920)  251  U.  S.  417. 

»"  United  States  v.  International  Harvester  Co.,  supra,  708. 

"  Ibid. 

«2  (1927)  274  U.  S.  693. 

291144 — 41— No.  3S 6 


74  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

matter  res  integra,  the  Court  was  limited,  by  the  form  of  the  sub- 
mission and  the  nature  of  its  review,  to  the  terms  of  the  decree  which 
the  Government  had  accepted  and  by  which  it  was  bound.  So  con- 
strued, the  value  of  the  decision  as  a  precedent  is  much  circumscribed. 
Wliile  it  must  be  admitted  that  the  issue  before  the  Court  was  rather 
narrow,  yet  the  right  of  the  Government  to  apply  for  further  relief 
to  bring  about  a  condition  "in  harmony  with  law"  had  been  expressly 
reserved  and  the  question  before  the  Court  was  whether  such  a  con- 
dition had  been  restored.  If  the  power  of  a  consolidated  company 
controlling  64  percent  of  the  industry  is  excessive  and  transcends 
the  limits  imposed  by  the  anti-trust  laws,  the  Court,  despite  the 
limited  scope  of  its  review,  had  ample  jurisdiction  to  modify  the  decree. 

Under  this  decision,  it  would  appear  that  the  abandonment  of 
a  wrongful  purpose  purges  the  combination  of  its  initial  unlawfulness. 
The  existence  of  monopoly  is  evidenced  by  a  control  over  prices  and 
the  absence  of  energetic  competition  by  independent  manufacturers. 
The  fact  that  independents  follow  the  price  leadership  of  the  dominant 
company  is  not,  standing  by  itself,  conclusive  on  the  question  of  con- 
trol. It  is  not  essential  that  the  aggregate  power  of  the  independents 
equals  that  of  the  combination  so  long  as  they  have  the  ability  and  are 
free  to  compete  with  the  combination.  If  there  be  such  competition, 
the  merger,  regardless  of  its  size,  is  lawful. 

The  existence  of  competition  in  the  industry  subsequent  to  the 
formation  of  the  combination  is  thus  regarded  as  more  significant  than 
an}'-  of  the  other  factors  stressed  in  the  previous  decisions.^^ 

11.    RECAPITULATION 

It  is  apparent  from  this  review  of  the  Supreme  Court  cases  that 
the  course  of  decision  in  the  field  of  mergers  and  consolidations  has 
been  erratic  and  unpredictable  and  that  there  is  today  virtually  as 
much  doubt  and  uncertainty  regarding  the  permissive  limits  of  capital 
combinations  as  there  was  in  1890.  Numerous  factors  which  may 
have  an  important  bearing  upon  the  legality  of  a  merger  of  two  or 
more  competing  companies  have  been  stressed  by  the  Court  and  the 
writers  on  the  subject.  A  recapitulation  of  the  Court  rulings  in 
terms  of  these  factors  may  be  fruitful  in  determining  whether  the 
decisions  permit  of  any  reliable  generalizations  concernmg  the  lawful 
limits  of  corporate  integrations. 

A.    SIZE   OF   THE   CAPITAL   COMBINATION   AND   ITS   POSITION   IN   THE    INDUSTRY 

Although  there  is  a  popular  belief  that  the  Sherman  Act  is  aimed 
primarily  at  bigness,  the  Supreme  Court  has  emphatically  stated 
on  two  occasions  that  the  size  of  a  capital  combination  is  not  of 
decisive  importance  in  determining  its  illegality.  Thus  in  the  Har- 
vester case  ^'*  Mr.  Justice  Sanford,  rephrasing  the  earlier  dictum  in  the 
Steel  case,^^  said: 

*  *  *  The  law,  however,  does  not  make  the  mere  size  of  a  corporation, 
however  impressive,  or  the  existence  of  unexerted  power  on  its  part,  an  offense, 
when  unaccompanied  by  unlawful  conduct  in  the  exercise  of  its  power.     *     *     * 

»3  For  similar  emphasis  upon  this  factor,  see  United  States  v.  Standard  Oil  Company  of  New  Jersey,  Standard 
Oil  Company  of  New  York,  and  the  \'acuvm  Oil  Company  (E.  D.  Mo.  1931),  47  F.  (2d)  288. 
"  United  States  v.  International  Harvester  Co.  (1927),  274  U.  S.  693,  708. 
M  United  States  v.  United  Staies  Steel  Corporation  (1920),  251  U.  S.  417,  451. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  75 

A  company  may  have  gigantic  resom-ces  and  immense  capitaliza- 
tion, but  being  pitted  against  other  giants  may  have  no  control  over 
price  or  industrial  policy.  Wliethcr  there  should  be  any  limitations 
on  corporate  size  is  dependent  upon  considerations  of  policy  extrinsic 
to  the  monopoly  problem.^^  Though  not  of  decisive  importance,  the 
element  of  size  may  not  be  ignored  in  determining  the  monopolistic 
power  of  any  combination.  The  Court  has  not  rejected  the  relevance 
of  size  in  proving  monopoly;  it  has  merely  held  that  size  by  itself  does 
not  constitute  a  violation  of  the  statute. 

It  is  difficult  to  believe  that  the  Court  regards  the  economic  posi- 
tion of  a  corporation  in  an  industry  or  its  control  of  the  market  as  of 
no  greater  importance  than  capitalization  or  net  worth,  although  its 
language  in  the  passage  above  quoted  is  capable  of  such  a  construc- 
tion. Such  a  view  would  strip  the  statute  of  its  meaning  and  efficacy, 
and  fortunately  the  Court  has  not  taken  this  position  in  its  other 
merger  decisions. 

A  few  preliminary  observations  are  essential  to  a  full  understanding 
of  the  significance  of  the  factor  of  market  control.  It  is  customary  to 
use  percentages  in  describing  the  economic  strength  of  a  capital  com- 
bination. The  use  of  numerical  figures  may,  however,  be  misleading. 
Many  businesses  defy  classification.  They  cannot  be  neatly  articu- 
lated in  any  well-recognized  industry.  An  industry  itself  is  a  tangle 
of  affairs,  sprawling,  disorderly,  and  with  ill-defined  borders.^^  Given 
one  definition  of  an  industry,  the  combine's  strength  may  be  impres- 
sive; with  another  definition  used  as  the  base,  its  power  may  slmnk 
to  insignificance.  Nor  can  the  matter  of  geography  be  ignored.  While 
exerting  monopolistic  influences  in  local  markets,  the  combine  may 
face  vigorous  competition  in  the  national  market.  Even  when  these 
factors  are  taken  into  account,  there  is  always  the  difficulty  of  obtain- 
ing accurate  statistical  information  concerning  the  relative  position 
of  the  enterprises  in  any  industry.  Percentages  based  upon  financial 
resources  or  productive  capacity  may  differ  from  those  based  upon 
output  or  sales  and  be  entitled  to  different  weight.  Degree  of  market 
control  is  thus  not  merely  a  matter  of  mathematical  computation;  it 
is  a  shorthand  expression  for  the  economic  strength  of  a  combine  in 
the  field  in  which  it  operates;  its  correct  determination  depends  upon 
the  weighting  of  all  the  relevant  factors. 

Wliat  importance  has  been  attributed  to  this  factor  in  the  decisions 
of  the  Supreme  Court?  Eight  capital  combinations  have  been  pro- 
nounced unlawful  by  the  Court.  The  percentage  of  the  industry  con- 
trolled by  the  combine  has  not  always  been  disclosed  by  the  opinion 
of  the  Court  or  by  the  record  of  the  case.  The  ascertainable  degree 
of  control  shows  a  variation  from  20  percent  in  the  case  of  Anthracite 
Coal  ^^  to  85  to  90  percent  in  the  case  of  oil.^^  The  Reading  combina- 
tion ^^  brought  within  the  control  of  a  single  holding  company  33}^ 
percent  of  the  anthracite  coal  marketed  in  the  country.  The  North- 
ern Securities,''^  the  Union  Pacific,''^  and  the  Southern  Pacific  ^  amal- 
gamations   combined    important    transcontinental    railroad    systems 

58  See  Mr.  Justice  Brandeis,  dissenting  in  Louis  K.  Liggett  Co.  v.  Lee  (1933),  288  U.  S.  517,  541, 548  et  seg. 

5'  See  Hamilton  and  Associates,  Price  and  Price  Policies  (1938).  sec.  1. 

5»  United  Staten  v.  Lehigh  Valley  Railroad  Co.  (1920\  254  U.  S.  255. 

«»  Standard  Oil  Company  of  New  Jersey  v.  United  States  (1911),  221  U.  S.  1. 

60  United  States  v.  Reading  Co.  (1920),  253  U.  S.  26. 

"  Northern  Securities  Company  v.  United  States  (1904),  193  U.  S.  197. 

62  United  States  v.  Union  Pacific  Railroad  Company  (1912),  226  U.  S.  61. 

«3  United  States  v.  Southern  Pacific  Company  (1922),  259  U.  S.  214. 


'JQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

which,  although  lacking  monopoly  power,  were  responsible  for  a  sub- 
stantial part  of  the  Nation's  transcontinental  traffic.  The  Terminal 
Railroad  case  ^^  dealt  with  a  monopoly  of  the  terminal  facilities  in  the 
city  of  St.  Louis.  The  American  Tobacco  combine  ^^  involved  a  cir- 
cular and  vertical  as  well  as  a  horizontal  integration,  the  degree  of 
control  varying  in  the  different  branches  of  the  industry  which  it 
dominated,  the  range  of  its  power  in  the  important  divisions  of  its 
business  extended  from  approximately  76  to  96  percent. 

Of  the  five  integrations  upheld  by  the  Supreme  Court,  four  con- 
trolled 50  percent  or  more  of  their  respective  industries.  The 
American  Sugar  Refining  Co.,^^  at  the  peak  of  its  power  was  respon- 
sible for  98  percent  of  the  sugar  refined  in  this  country.  The  per- 
centage of  control  of  the  United  Shoe  Machinery  Co.®^  exceeded  90 
percent.  The  United  States  Steel  Corporation  ^^  at  the  time  of  suit 
was  the  dominant  producer  of  steel  and  controlled  about  50  percent 
of  the  industry.  The  International  Harvester  Co.*^^  accounted  for 
64  percent  of  the  business  done  in  its  field.  The  copper  combine  ^°  is 
the  only  merger  uphold  embracing  less  than  50  percent  of  its  industry, 
its  percentage  being  22. 

The  same  variations  are  to  be  noted  in  the  State  and  lower  Federal 
court  decisions.''^ 

It  is  evident,  therefore,  both  from  a  careful  reading  of  the  opinions 
of  the  Court  and  from  a  comparison  of  these  figures,  that  the  degree 
of  control  is  not  the  decisive  factor  in  determining  the  legality  of 
capital  combinations. 

Although  the  decisions  cannot  be  reconciled  in  terms  of  any  mathe- 
matical formula,  it  is  doubtful  whether  the  Court  would  decline  to 
accord  considerable  weight  to  the  element  of  market  control.  Un- 
fortunately, tliis  factor  has  not  been  accorded  the  prominence  in 
judicial  ruling  which  it  clearly  merits.  A  construction  of  the  statute 
which  permits  one  company  to  control  64  percent  of  an  industry  has 
placed  the  wall  of  the  law's  protection  too  far  from  the  center  of  the 
monopoly  evil  to  have  any  real  salutary  economic  effect. 

The  Court  is  not  alone  at  fault  for  the  vagueness  and  inconsistency 
of  its  rulings.  Little  guidance  was  furnished  either  by  the  common 
law  development  of  the  monopoly  concept  or  by  the  legislative  history 
of  the  Sherman  law.  The  word  "monopoly"  was  not  defined  in  the 
legislation  and  the  broad  use  of  the  term  in  legislative  discussion  and 
popular  literature  afforded  no  reliable  clue  to  the  legislative  purpose. 
It  was  clear  that  Congress  intended  to  prohibit  concentration  of 
industrial  control  this  side  of  total  ownership  or  domination;  otherwise 
the  statute  would  have  little  meaning.  How  far  short?  The  Supreme 
Court,  unaided  by  history  and  unschooled  by  experience,  was  called 
upon  to  draw  the  line  somewhere  in  the  scale  from  0  to  100.  It 
naturally  eschewed  a  mathematical  approach  to  the  problem.  There 
are  other  factors  to  be  considered.  In  practice  the  facts  of  the 
pai'ticular  case  has  dominated  the  decision.  Each  case  is  thus  a 
law  unto  itself.     The  dividing  line  has  been  located  at  one  point  on 

«<  United  States  v.  Terminal  Rnilrond  Association  of  St.  Louis  (19n),  224  U.  S.  383. 

«'  United  States  v.  American  Tobacco  Company  (IQU),  221  U.  S.  IOC. 

"  United  States  v.  /•;.  C.  Kiiiijht  Co.  (1S9S),  15(';  U.  S.  1. 

«'  United  States  v.  Lhiiled  Sline  Machinery  Co.  of  New  Jersey  (1918),  247  U.  S.  32. 

«'  United  States  V.  United  States  Steel  Corporation  (1920),  251  U.  S.  417. 

«»  United  States  v.  International  Harvester  Co.  (1927),  274  U.  S.  693. 

"  Geddes  v.  Anaconda  Copper  Mining  Co.  (1921),  254  U.  S.  .590. 

"  See  Handler,  Industrial  Mergers  and  the  Anti-Trust  Laws  (1932),  32  Col.  L.  Rev.  179,  245. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  77 

the  scale  in  one  industry  and   elsewhere  in  another.     Clarity   and 
precision  of  doctrine  cannot  be  expected  in  such  a  l(^o;al  recrime. 

"Monoply"  under  the  statute  thus  means  that  degree  of  control 
which  the  Supreme  Court  deems  unlawful.  The  illicit  degree  of  con- 
trol is  an  unknown  quantity  and  obtains  its  meaning  from  the  tradi- 
tional process  of  judicial  inclusion  and  exclusion.  The  role  of  the 
Court  has  thus  far  been  experimenta).  It  has  groped  its  way  cauti- 
ously and  tentatively  in  an  effort  to  locate  the  dividing  line  at  a 
point  fair  to  all  the  interests  concerned.  The  results  thus  reached 
have  been  entirely  unsatisfactory.  The  prevailing  confusion  and  un- 
certainty, deplorable  though  they  may  be,  leave  both  the  Congress 
and  the  Court  free  to  ascribe  greater  weight  to  the  clement  of  market 
control,  by  the  adoption  of  a  series  of  rebuttable  presumptions  or  by 
the  formulation  of  a  more  definite  criterion  of  the  permissive  degree 
of  corporate  integration. 

B.    INTENT    TO    MONOPOLIZE 

The  element  most  emphasized  in  the  decisions  is  the  intent  to 
monopohze.  The  statute  does  not  directly  forbid  monopoly,  its 
penalties  are  imposed  upon  those  persons  who  "shall  monopolize  or 
attempt  to  monopolize  or  combine  or  conspire  with  any  other  person 
or  persons,  to  monopolize  any  part  of  the  trade  or  commerce  among 
the  several  States,  or  with  foreign  nations." 

A  plausible  argument  predicated  upon  the  wording  of  the  statute 
can  be  advanced  in  support  of  the  view  that  the  mental  element  is  an 
essential  part  of  the  statutory  offense.  Such  a  construction,  however, 
is  not  inescapable. 

Although  the  intent  to  monopolize  was  present  in  several  of  the 
combinations  held  violative  of  the  statute, ^^  such  intent  was  also 
present  in  at  least  two  decisions  in  which  the  Court  refused  to  order 
dissolution,  viz,  the  Knight  case,'^^  where  the  proponents  of  the  com- 
bination intended  to  monopolize  the  entire  sugar  refining  industry, 
and  in  the  Shoe  Machinery  cases, "^^  where  the  manifest  purpose  of  the 
defendants  was  to  control  the  shoe  machinery  industry.  And  there 
are  rulings  upholding  corporate  fusions  despite  the  existence  of  a 
wrongful  purpose  on  the  part  of  the  promoters  of  the  combine.  The 
moving  spirits  of  the  steel  ^^  and  copper  ^^  combines  intended  to  con- 
trol their  respective  industries.  Their  purposes,  however,  were  never 
achieved,  and  the  Court  found  that  the  intent  to  monopolize  had  been 
abandoned.  Several  combines  have  been  condemned  by  the  Court, 
notably  in  the  railroad  cases,"  in  the  absence  of  any  evidence  of  a 
monopolistic  purpose,  the  intent  of  the  parties  being  merely  to  unite 
competitive  properties.  Thus,  as  a  matter  of  authority,  it  can  be 
definitely  stated  that  the  element  of  intent  has  not  always  been 
decisive. ^^ 


'2  Standard  Oil  Company  of  New  Jersey  v.  United  States  (19U),  221  U.  S.  1;  United  States  v.  American 
Tobacco  Company  (1911),  221  U.  S.  lOG;  United  States  v.  Terminal  Railroad  Association  of  St.  Louis  (1912), 
224  U.  S.383. 

"  United  States  v.  E.  C.  Knight  Co.  (1895),  156  U.  S.  1. 

"  United  States  v.  Winslow  (1913),  227  U.  S.  202;  United  States  v.  United  Shoe  Machinery  Co.  of  New  Jersey 
(1917),  247  U.  S.32. 

"  United  States  v.  United  States  Steel  Corporation  (1920),  251  U.  S.  417. 

J9  Geddes  v.  Anaconda  Copper  Mining  Co.  (1921),  254  U.  S.  59. 

"  United  States  v.  Union  Pacific  Railway  Company  (1912),  226  U.  S.  61;  United  States  v.  Southern  Pacific 
Company  (1922),  259  U.  S.  214;  Northern  Securities  Company  v.  United  States  (1904),  193  U.  S.  197. 

"  But  cf.  United  States  v.  Socony-Vacuvm  Oil  Co.,  Inc.,  (i940),  310  U.  S.  150,  224,  n.  59. 


yg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

This  is  not  at  all  surprising.  Since  a  person  must  be  held  account- 
able for  the  necessary  consequences  of  his  conduct,  one  who  attains  a 
monopoly  position  can  hardly  be  permitted  to  deny  his  monopolistic 
purpose.  Where  monopoly  exists,  the  intent  to  monopolize  is  con- 
clusively presumed,'''^  and  thus,  as  a  practical  matter,  is  not  a  factor 
of  any  consequence.  Where  the  intent  to  monopolize,  though  present^ 
is  ineffectual,  the  tendency  is  for  the  courts  to  find  that  the  intent  has 
been  abandoned  and  to  give  it  no  weight.  In  the  borderline  cases, 
where  it  is  difficult  in  fact  to  determine  whether  monopoly  control  has 
been  attained,  the  element  of  intent  may  become  decisive.^" 

In  short,  whatever  may  be  the  theoretical  significance  of  the  mental 
element  in  the  monopoly  cases,  in  point  of  authority,  the  element  is 
inconsequential,  both  where  the  combination  clearly  possesses  and 
clearly  lacks  monopoly  control.  In  such  cases,  it  is  the  presence  or 
absence  of  monopoly  power  in  fact  which  is  important.  It  is  only  in 
the  borderline  cases  that  the  mental  element  may  be  legally  signifi- 
cant. 

Wliatever  may  be  its  importance  in  theory  and  as  a  matter  of 
authority,  the  issue  of  intent  is  generally  tendered  by  the  defendants 
in  monopoly  litigation  and  the  Government  thus  feels  obliged  to 
establish  the  wrongful  purposes  of  the  defendants.  Though  a  close 
analysis  of  the  opinions  of  the  Supreme  Coiu't  indicates  that  intent 
is  not  an  essential  element  in  the  offense  of  monopoly,  in  the  absence 
of  any  clear  authority  declaring  intent  an  inconsequential  factor,  it 
would  appear  to  be  desirable  in  any  statutory  revision  to  consider 
whether,  as  a  matter  of  policy,  the  Government  in  antitrust  litigation 
should  be  required  to  prove  guilty  purpose  on  the  part  of  the  defend- 
ants.^^ 

To  adopt  a  purely  subjective  test  of  legality  in  the  complicated 
field  of  industrial  integration  would  seem  unwise.  The  proponents 
of  any  combination  always  profess  the  most  exalted  motives.  Since 
their  hearts  and  minds  cannot  be  searched  by  the  Court,  the  Govern- 
ment, in  the  absence  of  admissions,  must  rely  upon  the  objective  fncts 
for  contradiction.  To  infer  intent  from  extrinsic  circumstances  is  to 
add  another  link  to  the  chain  of  proof  and  to  open  the  door  to  meta- 
physical distinctions,  evasion,  and  further  uncertainty. 

The  antitrust  laws  should  be  concerned  not  with  a  state  of  mind 
but  with  economic  realities.  It  is  the  existence  of  monopoly,  and  not 
the  reasons  which  prompted  those  responsible  for  its  creation,  which 
calls  for  corrective  action. ^^ 

"  This  was  expressed  bv  Mr.  Justice  Lurton  in  United  Stales  v.  Reading  Company  (1912),  226  U.  S.  324, 
370: 

"Whether  a  particular  act,  contract  or  agreement  was  a  reasonable  and  normal  method  in  fiirtheranee  of 
trade  and  commerce  may,  in  doubtful  cases,  turn  upon  the  intent  to  he  inferred  from  the  extent  of  the  con- 
trol thereby  secured  over  the  commerce  affected,  as  well  as  by  the  method  which  was  used.  Of  course,  if 
the  necessary  result  is  materially  to  restrain  trade  between  the  States,  the  intent  with  which  the  thing  was 
done  is  of  no  consequence.  But  when  there  is  only  a  probability,  the  intent  to  produce  the  consequences 
may  become  important.     *    *    *" 

8»  See  United  States  v.  Reading  Company  (•1912),  226  U.  S.  324.  370. 

'1  In  suits  under  sec.  1  charging  a  restraint  of  trade,  it  is  settled  by  authoritative  pronouncement  of  the 
Supreme  Court  tliat  wrongful  intent  need  not  be  established  by  the  Government  and  that  good  motives 
will  not  condone  action  in  contravention  of  the  statute.  See  Standard  Sanitary  Manufacturing  Company  v. 
United  s/ales  fl9I2)  226  U.  S.  20,  49;  United  Slates  v.  Socony-Vacuum  Oil  Co.  "(1940'>,  310  U.  S.  150,  220,  221, 
228;  United  Slates  v.  Trenton  Potteries  (1927).  273  U.  S.  392,  395. 

82  Kccent  reports  of  the  .\ttoriu\v  (icneral  have  forcefully  called  attention  to  the  debilitating  effects  of  the 
requirement  that  wronuful  intent  or  guilty  imrpose  be  establishe<l  and  have  pointed  out  that  one  of  the 
factors  contributing  to  the  failure  of  tlie  Sliennan  law  has  been  llie  iuijiortation  of  moral  considerations  into 
the  construction  and  enforcement  of  the  statute.     Report  of  Attorney  General  (1938)  p.  3;  id.  (1939)  p.  '37. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  79 

C.  INDULGENCE  IN  PREDATORY  PRACTICES 

It  has  been  sug:g:ested  by  the  Supreme  Court  ^^  that  the  statute  is 
concerned  more  with  the  improper  exercise  than  the  mere  existence  of 
monopoly  power.  The  emphasis  upon  the  brutal  practices  of  the 
Oil  ^*  and  Tobacco  ^^  Trusts,  coupled  with  the  importance  ascribed  to 
the  absence  of  any  overt,  repressive  acts  and  abuse  of  power  in  the 
Steel  case,^^  has  led  to  the  popular  distinction  between  "o;ood"  and 
"bad"  trusts.  Implicit  in  this  distinction  is  the  notion  that  legahty 
depends  in  a  laro;e  measure  upon  whether  the  combination  has  indulged 
in  predatory  practices. 

The  term,  predatory  practices,  requires  definition.  "Predatoiy" 
may  mean  either  brutal,  overt  acts  by  which  competition  is  suppressed, 
or  any  conduct  violative  of  the  antitrust  laws  or  other  laws  regulating 
business  competition. 

Although  some  of  the  unlawful  trusts  were  guilty  of  predatory 
conduct  in  the  first  or  narrow  sense, *^  several  combines  have  been 
held  unlawful  in  the  absence  of  any  evidence  of  improper  competitive 
conduct,  no  matter  how  broadly  the  term  "predatory"  is  used.  There 
was  no  evidence  of  overt  acts,  abuse  of  power,  exclusion  of  competitors, 
exaction  of  monopoly  profits,  discrimination,  price-cutting,  or  artifi- 
cial restrictions  on  potential  competition  in  about  half  the  reported 
cases  in  which  combinations  were  held  unlawful. ^^  On  the  other  hand, 
there  was  evidence  of  unfair  conduct  in  some  cases  in  which  the 
combinations  were  upheld. ^^  While  not  brutal,  the  behavior  of  the 
combines  in  these  cases  was  no  less  "predatory"  than  the  practices 
in  some  of  the  instances  in  which  trusts  have  been  condemned.  It 
is  thus  apparent  that  proof  of  the  improper  exercise  of  monopoly 
power  is  not  a  prerequisite  of  illegality. 

The  matter  can  be  further  tested  hypothetically.  No  matter  how 
unlawful  and  brutal  its  practices  may  be,  a  combination  controlling 
less  than  10  percent  of  an  industry  would  hardly  be  held  to  be  an 
unlawful  monopoly.  On  the  other  hand,  a  combination  controlling  an 
entire  industry  could  not  escape  dissolution  by  virtue  of  the  fact  that  it 
had  eliminated  competition  by  purchase  of  its  competitors  rather  than 
through  resort  to  methods  suppressive  of  competition. 

As  in  the  case  of  intent,  the  element  of  predatory  conduct  may  be  of 
great  importance  as  a  practical  matter  in  borderline  cases,  but  the 
conclusion  is  inescapable,  from  a  careful  reading  of  the  authorities, 
that  the  lawfulness  of  a  merger  or  consolidation  does  not  depend  upon 
the  presence  or  absence  of  such  conduct.  Here  also,  to  condition 
legality  upon  this  extrinsic  factor  would  be  to  introduce  moral  con- 
siderations into  antitrust  enforcement.  Monopoly  is  reprehensible  in 
a  political  democracy  whether  or  not  accompanied  by  evil  purpose  or 
improper  conduct.  There  is  no  reason  why  monopoly  and  predatory 
behavior  should  not  be  both  outlawed,  whether  they  occur  separately 
or  in  combination.     Notwithstanding    the  contrary   dictum   of   the 

83  United  States  v.  United  States  Steel  Corporation  (1920),  251  U.  S.  417;  United  Slates  v.  International  Har 
vester  Co.  (1927),  274  U.  S.  693. 

64  Standard  Oil  Company  of  Neiv  Jersey  v.  United  States  (1911),  221  U.  S.  1. 

S5  United  States  v.  American  Tobacco  Company  (1911),  221  U.  S.  106. 

8s  United  States  v.  United  States  Steel  Corporation  (1920),  251  U.  S.  417. 

^T  Standard  Oil  Company  of  New  Jersey  v.  United  States  (1911),  221  U.  S.  1;  United  States  v.  American 
Tobacco  Company.  (1911)  221  U.  S.  106. 

88  See  Handler,  Industrial  Mergers  and  the  Anti-Trust  Laws  (1932),  32  Col.  L.  Rev.  179,  252. 

8»  Handler,  Industrial  Mergers  and  the  Anti-Trust  Laws  (1932),  32  Col.  L.  Rev.  179,  251. 


§Q  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Court  in  the  Harvester  case,^°  quoted  above,  it  is  inferable  from  the 
authorities  as  a  whole  that  both  are  equally  inhibited  by  the  statute. 
The  distinction  between  good  and  bad  trusts  belongs  to  that  out- 
moded era  when  the  antitrust  laws  were  regarded  as  a  moral  pro- 
nouncement rather  than  a  charter  of  economic  freedom. 

D.    MONOPOLY    POWER    TO    EXCLUDE     COMPETITORS    OR    TO     FIX    PRICES 

Although  combinations  have  been  held  unlawful  which  lacked 
either  the  power  to  exclude  competitors  or  to  fix  the  market  price,®^ 
the  cases  frequently  advert  to  the  power  of  the  defendants  to  exclude 
competitors  or  to  fix  prices.  How  the  existence  of  such  power  is  to 
be  determined  is  not  disclosed.  It  will  hardly  be  denied  that  he  who 
can  exclude  his  competitors,  and,  without  the  cooperation  of  rival 
sellers,  can  determine  the  market  price,  enjoys  monopoly  control;  but 
the  determination  of  the  existence  of  such  power  is  no  less  difficult  than 
the  proof  of  monopoly  itself.  What  degree  of  control  is  necessary  to 
enable  one  to  exclude  competitors  or  establish  the  market  price? 

By  posing  the  issue  in  terms  of  the  power  of  exclusion  and  the 
power  to  fix  the  market  price,  the  lines  of  inquiry  are  better  marked 
and  analysis  can  be  more  pointed.  But  apart  from  its  better  restate- 
ment, the  problem  remains  unsolved.  It  is  no  easier  from  either  a 
legal  or  an  economic  standpoint  to  determine  whether  the  jurisdiction 
of  a  company  over  price  is  monopolistic  than  it  is  to  determine  whether 
the  company  is  a  monopoly. 

Evidence  revealing  the  exclusion  of  competitors  or  the  control  of 
prices  in  fact  is  strong  and  convincing  proof  of  the  existence  of  monop- 
oly power.  But  such  power  may  be  present  though  proof  of  its 
improper  exercise  may  be  lacking  or  difficult  of  establishment  in  a 
court  of  law.  As  has  been  pointed  out,  the  existence  of  monopoly 
power,  regardless  of  the  manner  of  its  exercise,  deprives  the  public  of 
the  benefits  of  free  competition,  and  hence  should  not  be  tolerated. 

E.   EXISTENCE   OF  ACTUAL  COMPETITION  IN  THE  INDUSTRY  AFTER  THE   COMPLETION 

OF   THE    MERGER 

Monopoly  is  sometimes  defined  as  the  absence  of  competition,  and 
the  contention  is  frequently  advanced  in  anti-trust  suits  that  the 
presence  of  unrestricted  competition  in  the  industry  negates  the 
existence  of  any  monopoly.  This  appears  to  have  been  the  criterion 
applied  in  the  Steel, ^^  Harvester, ^^  and  the  Standard  Oil-Vacuum  cases. ^'^ 

Here  again  we  are  dealing  with  a  factor  whose  importance  is 
ambiguous  under  the  authorities.  It  is  true  that  there  was  no  outside 
competition  in  the  case  of  some  unlawful  combinations,^^  and  that 
there  was  outside  competition  in  some  of  the  combines  upheld  by  the 
courts.^^     On  the  other  hand,  there  are  several  instances  of  combines 

<">  United  States  v.  International  Harvester  Co.  (1027),  274  U.  S.  693,  708. 

••  Northern  Securities  ( 'ompain/  v.  i'liilcd  Stales  (1904),  193  U.  S.  197;  United  States  v.  Union  Pacific  Railroad 
Company  (1912),  220  U.  S.  (;i;  ( -iiited  Sliilcs  v.  Soulliern  Pacific  Company  (1922),  259  U.  S.  214;  United  States  v. 
Readinci  Company  (1920),  253  IJ.  S.  26;  United  States  v.  Lehic/li  Valley  Railroad  Co.  (1920),  254  U.  S.  255. 

•2  UnilKl  Slates  v.  United  States  Steel  Corporation  (1920),  251  U.  S.  417. 

«3  United  Slates  v.  International  Harvester  Co.  (1927),  274  U.  S.  093. 

"  United  Slates  v.  Standard  Oil  Co.  of  New  Jersey  (E.  D.  Mo.  1931),  47  F.  (2d)  288. 

^''Standard  Oil  Company  of  New  Jersey  v.  United  States  (1911),  221  U.  S.  1;  United  States  v.  American 
Tobacco  Company,  (1911)  221  U.  S.  100;  United  States  v.  Terminal  Railroad  Association  of  St.  Louis,  (1912) 
224  U.  S.  383. 

»«  United  States  v.  United  States  Steel  Corporation  (1920),  251  IT.  S.  417;  United  Slates  v.  International  Har- 
vester Co.,  (1927)  274  U.  S.  693;  United  States  v.  Standard  Oil  Company  of  New  Jersey,  Standard  Oil  Co.  of 
New  York,  and  the  Vacuum  Oil  Company  (E.  D.  Mo.  1931),  47  F.  (2d)  288. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  gi 

which,  although  subject  to  effective  outside  competition,  were  con- 
demned by  the  courts.®^  And  there  are  also  instances  of  combines 
which,  though  not  subject  to  outside  competition,  were  nevertheless 
upheld  by  the  coui'ts,^^ 

This  factor  is  more  attractive  than  any  of  the  other  criteria  that 
have  been  suggested  for  the  determination  of  the  legality  of  corporate 
integrations.  If  there  is  outside  competition,  actual  as  well  as  poten- 
tial, monopoly  power  cannot  be  exerted,  the  evils  of  monopoly  are 
avoided,  and  the  public  is  adequately  protected.  The  simplicity  of 
the  test  is  delusive  and  there  are  serious  impediments  to  its  practical 
application.  What  constitutes  vigorous  and  effective  competition? 
Under  what  circumstances  can  it  be  said  that  the  independents  are 
able  to  compete  on  a  parity  with  the  combination?  When  the  inde- 
pendents enter  into  price-fixing  agreements  with  the  combination  or 
follow  its  price  leadersliip,  is  their  competition  free?  When  the 
independents  are  conscious  of  the  power  of  the  combination  to  crush 
them  at  will,  are  they  competing  on  an  equal  basis?  These  are  not 
legal  questions.  Nor  are  they  questions  of  fact  wliich  an  untrained 
mind  can  resolve.  The  details  are  multitudinous,  the  facts  of  per- 
plexing intricacy. 

The  Supreme  Court  has  not  been  notably  successful  in  the  handling 
of  such  issues.  The  manner  in  which  it  evaluated  the  evidence  of 
competition  in  the  Steel  case  ^^  is  open  to  criticism  from  the  viewpoint 
of  the  economist.  In  the  Harvester  case,^  it  rejected  the  conclusions 
of  the  economists  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  as  being  based  on 
ex  parte  statements  and  hearsay.  To  use  statistical  data  in  court 
without  running  afoul  of  the  hearsay  rule  is  a  rare  feat  of  prestidigi- 
tation. 

The  present  machinery  of  court  litigation  is  not  well  adapted  to 
the  thoroughgoing  economic  study  which  is  essential  to  a  proper 
determination  of  the  existence,  strength,  and  efficacy  of  outside  com- 
petition. Perhaps  this  criterion  could  be  better  applied  adminis- 
tratively. In  any  event,  it  has  not  been,  under  the  authorities,  the 
decisive  element  in  antitrust  litigation. 

F.    POTENTIAL    COMPETITION 

Although  there  are  those  who  feel  that  the  public  is  adequately 
safeguarded  if  potential  competition  remains  free  and  unfettered  at 
all  times,  the  Sherman  law  demands  that  actual  as  well  as  potential 
competition  be  uncurbed.  The  complete  elimination  of  competition 
is  unlawful  even  in  a  field  entirely  open  to  new  enterprise  and  capital. 
The  contrary  dictum  in  the  Terminal  case  ^  is  without  support  in  the 
other  authorities.  Many  of  the  mergers  condemned  by  the  Supreme 
Court  imposed  no  restrictions  on  potential  competition.  Not  only 
was  such  competition  likely,  but  the  subsequent  history  of  these 
industries  reveals  the  rise  of  many  new  enterprises.^     The  likelihood 

«'  United  States  v.  Reading  Company  (1920),  253  U.  S.  26;  United  States  v.  Lehigh  Valley  Railroad  Co.  (1920), 
254  U.  S.  255;  Uiiited  Slates  v.  Union  Pacific  Company  (1912),  226  U.  S.  61;  United  States  v.  Southern  Pacific 
Company  (1922),  259  U.  S.  214. 

•8  United  States  v.  Winslow  (1913),  227  U.  S.  202;  United  States  v.  United  Shoe  Machinery  Co.  of  New  Jersey, 
(1917)  247  U.  S.  32. 

»9  Uriited  States  v.  United  States  Steel  Corporation  (1920),  251  U.  S.  417. 

1  United  States  v.  International  Harvester  Co.  (1927),  274  U.  S.  693. 

s  United  States  v.  Terminal  Railroad  Association  of  St.  Louis  (1912),  224  U.  S.  383,  405. 

3  See  Handler,  Industrial  Mergers  and  the  Anti-Trust  Laws  (1932),  32  Col.  L.  Rev.  179,  258. 


§2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

of  potential  competition  thus  falls  down  as  a  test  of  legality.  A 
combination  may  be  held  unlawful  even  though  new  competition  is 
unrestricted.  Thus,  again  we  have  a  factor  which,  though  of  un- 
doubted importance,  does  not  explain  the  divergent  court  rulings. 

Suppose  on  the  other  hand,  that  such  restraints  have  been  imposed. 
Does  this  taint  the  combination  with  illegality?  Only  those  organi- 
zations already  possessing  monopoly  control  can  effectively  restrict 
potential  competition.  Moreover,  wherever  the  field  is  thus  closed 
to  new  enterprise,  many  of  the  other  factors  discussed  above  are  apt 
to  be  present.  A  combmation,  therefore,  that  possesses  and  exercises 
the  power  to  exclude  new  competition  is  probably  unlawful,  for  this 
and  other  reasons. 

The  interesting  case  is  where  no  restraints  are  imposed  by  the  com- 
bination, but  the  entry  of  new  capital  is  extremely  unlikely  for  either 
economic  or  physical  reasons.  This  was  essentially  the  situation  in 
the  Terminal  case;  ■*  in  fact  the  Court  believed  it  was  impossible  for 
new  competition  to  arise.  The  situation  in  the  Shoe  Machinery  case  ^ 
was  not  very  different,  but  the  point  was  not  strongly  urged.  If 
existing  competition  is  vigorous,  it  is  doubtful  whether  the  combination 
will  be  declared  unlawful  merely  because  it  is  difficult  for  new  com- 
panies to  enter  the  field.  But  where  actual  competition  is  ineffective 
and  new  competition  unlikely  or  unpossible,  the  combination  in  all 
probability,  despite  the  Shoe  Machinery  case,^  will  be  forbidden. 

G.    FORM    OF    COMBINATION 

The  decisions  cannot  be  reconciled  m  terms  of  the  form  taken  by 
the  combination.  Trusts,  holding  companies,  stock  acquisitions,  and 
outright  purchases  of  property  and  other  assets  have  been  all  held 
unlawful.^  It  is  interesting  to  observe  that  the  trusts  condemned  all 
possessed  a  very  high  degree  of  control  of  their  industries.  This  was 
also  true  of  most  of  the  holding  companies  which  were  found  to  violate 
the  statute.^  The  most  severe  application  of  the  Sherman  Act  has 
been  m  cases  involving  stock  acquisitions.^  Nevertheless,  the  dictum 
in  the  American  Tobacco  case  that  "the  mere  form  in  which  the  assailed 
transactions  are  clothed  becomes  of  no  moment"  ^^  is  essentially  true 
of  proceedings  under  the  Sherman  Act,  whatever  may  be  the  im- 
portance of  corporate  forms  in  Clayton  Act  litigation. 

H.    OTHER   JUSTIFICATIONS 

Attempts  to  justify  combinations  exceeding  the  permitted  degree 
of  concentration  on  the  ground  that  prices  have  been  reduced,"  the 
quality  of  the  article  improved,^-  service  bettered, ^^  competitors  fairly 
treated/^  or  that  the  purpose  of  the  combination  was  to  avoid  the 

*  United  States  v.  Terminal  Railroad  Association  of  St.  Louis  (1912),  224  U.  S.  383. 

»  United  States  v.  Winslotv  (1913),  227  U.  S.  202. 

»  Ibid. 

'  See  Handler,  Industrial  Mergers  and  the  Anti-Trust  Laws  (1932),  32  Col.  L.  Rev.  179,  259  et  seg. 

«  The  exceptions  arc:  Norttiern  Securities  v.  United  States  (1904),  193  U.  S.  197;  United  States  v.  Reading 
Company  (1920),  253  U.  S.  20;  United  States  v.  LeMigli  Vallev  Railroad  Co.  (1920),  254  U.  S.  255. 

^United  States  v.  Soiitliern  Pacific  Company  (1922),  259  U.  S.  214;  United  States  v.  Union  Pacific  Railroad 
Company  (1912),  220  U.  S.  61. 

'O  United  States  v.  American  Tobacco  Company  (1911),  221  U.  S.  106,  180. 

»  Northern  Securities  Company  v.  United  States  (1904),  193  U.  S.  197. 

'2  State  V.  Standard  Oil  (Ohio  1892),  30  N.  E.  279,  290. 

'3  United  Slates  v.  Great  Lakes  Towing  Company  (N.  D.  Ohio  1913),  208  Fed.  733,  decree  (N.  D.  Ohio  1914), 
217  Fed.  656.  appeal  dismissed  on  motion  of  United  States  (1917),  245  U.  S.  675. 

><  United  States  v.  International  Harvester  Company  (D.  Minn.  1914),  214  Fed.  987, 993,  appeal  dismissed  on 
motion  of  appellants  (1918),  248  U.  S.  587,  supplemental  bill  (1927),  274  U.  S.  693. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  83 

excesses  of  the  fierce  competition  tliat  preceded  the  forniatioii  '^  have 
all  been  unsucccssfuL  Despite  all  the  emphasis  on  intent,  th(>,  courts 
have  been  disinclined  to  inquire  into  the  motives  of  the  proponents 
of  the  combination. 

Yet,  in  some  of  the  cases,  the  economic  effects  of  the  combination 
have  been  considered  and  the  efficiencies  of  the  new  company  stressed.'^ 
A  contrary  attitude  has  also  been  maiufested.'^  Theoretically,  the 
upper  limit  of  a  combination  should  n(^ver  exceed  the  point  of  highest 
economic  efficiency.  Such  a  test  is  difficult  of  practical  application. 
The  facts  are  not  easily  ascertained,  the  evidence  is  apt  to  be  con- 
flicting and  speculative,  and  the  conclusions  imcertain.  In  any  event 
the  courts  have  not  purported,  except  in  rare  instances,  to  apply 
any  such  test. 

The  most  frequent  justification  has  been  the  insolvency  of  the 
selling  company  or  the  imperative  need  for  financial  readjustment.'* 
By  permitting  combinations  under  such  circumstances,  the  courts 
may  be  opening  an  inviting  field  for  subterfuge. 

The  existence  of  other  forms  of  governmental  regulation  has  been 
considered  a  justification  for  monopoly  power,  notably  in  the  public 
utilit}^  field. '^  Where  the  combined  companies  are  not  in  competition 
with  each  other,  the  union  has  generally  been  upheld.^* 

12.    RULE  OF  REASON  IN  MONOPOLY  CASES 

We  have  seen  that  the  adoption  of  the  rule  of  reason  had  little 
perceptible  eft'ect  on  the  doctrine  of  restraint  of  trade  applicable  to 
loose-knit  confederations.  As  the  Supreme  Court  passed  upon  but 
two  capital  combinations  before  the  promulgation  of  the  rule  of  reason, 
upholding  the  combine  in  the  Knight  case,~^  and  condemning  it  in  the 
Northern  Securities  case^  it  is  not  fruitful  to  contrast  the  decisions 
before  with  those  after  the  adoption  of  the  rule. 

The  standard  of  reason  has  permitted  the  Court  to  sit  as  a  censor 
on  corporate  integrations  and  undoubtedly  has  resulted  in  a  more 
tolerant  attitude  toward  such  combines  than  would  have  been  the 
case  had  the  rule  of  reason  been  rejected.  Once  it  was  decided  that 
the  statute  does  not,  on  the  one  hand,  prohibit  every  business  con- 
solidation, nor  permit,  on  the  other,  integrations  just  short  of  complete 
domination,  the  Court,  with  or  without  a  rule  of  reason,  was  com- 
pelled to  draw  the  Ime  somewhere  in  the  scale  from  1  to  100  percent. 
The  rule  of  reason  has  not  altered  the  nature  of  the  problem  with 
which  the  courts  have  been  confronted  and,  except  for  its  doubtful 
psychological  value,  has  not  assisted  the  courts  in  the  formulation 
of  any  clear  and  predictable  tests  by  which  the  legaUty  of  corporate 
integrations  might  be  measured.     Little  would  thus  be  accomplished 

15  State  V.  International  Harvester  Company  of  America,  237  Mo.  369,  383,  384,  391,  affirmed  (1914),  234  U.  S. 
199 

16  United  States  v.  United  States  Steel  Corporation  (1920),  251  U.  S.  417,  443;  cf.  United  States  v.  Terminal 
Railroad  Association  of  St.  Louis  (1912),  224  U.  S.  383,  410. 

1'  Northern  Securities  Company  v.  United  States  (1904),  193  U.  S.  197,  327  et  seq.;  United  States  v.  Union 
Pacific  Railroad  Company  (1912),  226  U.  S.  61,  87  et  seg. 

'8  United  States  v.  United  States  Steel  Corporation  (1920),  251  U.  S.  417  (with  regard  to  the  acquisition  of 
the  Tennessee  company);  Lumbermen's  Trust  Co.  v.  Title  Insurance  Company  (C.  C.  A.  9th,  1918),  248 
Fed.  212:  United  States  v.  Quaker  Oats  Company  (N.  D.  111.  1916),  232  Fed.  499;  Northivestern  Consolidated 
Milling  Co.  v.  Callam  (C.  C.  E.  D.  Mich.  1910),  177  Fed.  786. 

19  Continental  Securities  Company  v.  Interborough  Rapid  Transit  Company  (C.  C.  A.  2d,  1915),  221  Fed. 
44;  Doherty  &  Company  v.  Rice  (C.  C,  M.  D.  Ala.  1910),  186  Fed.  204,amrmed  (C.  C.  A.  5th,  1911),  184  Fed. 
878 

'0  United  States  v.  Winslow  (1912),  227  U.  S.  202;  United  States  v.  United  Shoe  Machinery  Co.  of  New  Jersey 
0917).  247  U.  S.32. 

21  United  States  v.  E.  C.  Knight  Co.  (1895),  156  U.  S.  1. 

22  Northern  Securities  Company  v.  United  States  (1904),  193  U.  S.  197. 


54  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

by  the  repeal,  judicial  or  legislative,  of  the  rule  of  reason  in  its  appli- 
cation to  mergers  and  consolidations.  Other  than  a  possible  tighten- 
ing of  the  lines,  such  a  repeal  of  itself  would  not  make  the  law  less 
confused  or  more  predictable  than  it  now  is. 

13.    DISSOLUTION 

We  have  not  undertaken  a  study  of  the  efficacy  of  the  various 
dissolution  decrees  which  have  been  entered  in  important  antitrust 
litigations.  It  is  common  knowledge,  however,  fortified  by  the  find- 
ings of  Government  agencies  ^^  and  private  investigators,^^  that  the 
decrees  have  rarely  succeeded  in  restoring  competition.  Although 
their  immediate  effects  have  been  negligible,  in  some  instances  there 
has  been  a  recrudescence  of  competition  after  a  lapse  of  many  years. ^^ 

Dissolution  decrees  could  undoubtedly  be  made  more  effective. ^^ 
A  decree  of  dissolution,  if  too  drastic,  may  have  catastrophic  effects 
upon  investors,  workers,  and  consumers  and  may,  in  case  of  our  basic 
industries,  unsettle  our  entire  economy.  Indeed,  one  cannot  read 
the  opinion  in  the  Steel  case  ^^  without  obtaining  the  firm  impression 
that  the  Court's  apprehensions  of  the  adverse  economic  effects  of 
dissolution  were  in  part  responsible  for  its  doubtful  construction  and 
application  of  the  law. 

Attempts  to  strengthen  the  dissolution  procedure  were  made  in  the 
legislation  of  1914.^^  Little  resort  has,  however,  been  made  to  these 
provisions  and  their  effect  has  been  negligible. 

The  processes  of  dissolution  can  unquestionably  be  strengthened^ 
but  the  question  arises  whether  it  is  not  better  through  new  legisla- 
tion to  prevent  undue  concentration  of  economic  power  than  to  stream- 
line the  procedure  for  unscrambling  the  eggs  after  the  evil  has  occurred. 

14.    RELATION  OF  MONOPOLY  TO  RESTRAINT  OF  TRADE 

Although  Chief  Justice  White  in  the  Standard  Oil  case  treated  re- 
straint of  trade  as  synonymous  with  monopoly,^^  there  are  vital  distinc- 

'3  Federal  Trade  Commission,  Agricultural  Implement  and  Machinery  Industry  (1938),  20,  164,  1037. 

2<  Hale,  Trust  Dissolution:  "Atomizing"  Business  Units  of  Monopolistic  Size  (1940),  40  Col.  L.  Rev. 
615,  623;  Cox,  Compilation  in  the  American  Tobacco  Industry  (1933)  21. 

25  Id.  at  618,  622;  Handler,  Cases  and  Materials  on  Trade  Regulation  (1937)  480. 

'9  The  decrees  could  provide  that  in  the  process  of  dissolution  the  stock  of  the  member  companies  may 
not  be  distributed  to  the  same  persons.  Some  action  might  also  be  taken  to  prevent  the  situation  which 
obtains  where  each  of  the  member  companies  after  dissolution  operates,  in  the  same  territory  as  it  did  when 
part  of  the  unlawful  combine,  without  the  competition  from  any  of  the  other  member  companies.  See 
Handler,  Cases  and  Materials  on  Trade  Regulation  (1937),  479. 

2'  Vnited  Stales  v.  United  States  Sted  Corporation  (1920).  251  U.  S.  417. 

2«  Sec.  7  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act  of  1914,  38  Stat.  722,  15  U.  S.  C.  sec.  47  (1934).  By  virtue 
of  sec.  6  (c)  of  the  same  act,  38  Stat.  721,  15  U.  S.  C.  sec.  46  (c)  (1934),  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  is 
required,  on  application  of  the  Attorney  General,  to  make  an  investigation  of  the  manner  in  which  a  dis- 
solution decree  is  being  carried  out.  Sec.  6  (e),  38  Stat.  721, 15  U.  S.  C.  sec.  46  (e)  (1934),  requires  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission  on  ajjplication  of  the  Attorney  General  to  make  recommendations  for  altering  a  business 
whicli  is  thought  to  be  violating  the  anti-trust  laws. 

Bibliography:  For  a  thorough  treatment  of  the  post-litigation  history  of  the  oil  industry  and  the  effective- 
ness of  the  decree  in  Standard  Oil  Co.  of  h'eu'  Jersey  v.  United  States  (1911),  221  U.  S.  1,  see  Stocking,  The  Oil 
Industry  and  the  Competitive  System  (1925),  chs.  V  and  VI:  Burns,  The  Decline  of  Competition  (1936) 
103  et  seq.  For  an  analysis  of  the  proceedincs  in  the  anthracite  coal  cases  see  (1932).  41  Yale  L.  J.  439:  As  to 
the  ell'cctiveness  of  the  decrees  in  United  States  v.  E.  I.  du  Pont  de  Nemours  &  Co.  (C.  C.  Del.  1911),  188  Fed. 
127,  see  Stevens,  The  Powder  Trust,  1872-1912  (1912),  26  Quar.  J.  Econ.  444;  id..  Dissolution  of  the  Powder 
Trust  (1912),  27  Quar.  J.  Econ.  202;  Laidler,  Concentration  in  American  Industry  (1936),  306-309;  Jones, 
Trust  Problem  in  the  United  States  (1920)  474-475;  Seager  and  Gulick,  Trust  and  Corporation  Problems 
(1929)  406-408:  Hancv.  Business  Organization  and  Combination  (3d  ed.  1934)  244-245;  in  United  States  v. 
En.'<linnn  Kodak  Co.  (W.  D.  N.  Y.  1913),  226  Fed.  62,  decree  (W.  D.  N.  Y.  1915),  230  Fed.  522.  appeal  dis- 
missed on  motion  of  the  appellant  (1921),  255  U.  S.  .578,  41  Sup.  Ct.  321;  see  Jones,  op.  cit.,  495,  hOi,  519; 
and  in  United  States  v.  Corn  Products  Refining  Co.  (S.  D.  N.  Y.  1916),  234  Fed.  964,  appeal  withdrawn, 
defendant  consenting  to  decree  see  Dewing,  Corporate  Promotions  and  Reorganizations  (1914)  49-111; 
Watkins,  Industrial  Combinations  and  Public  Policy  (1927)  201-220;  Jones,  op.  cit.,  296,  436-438,  484-485; 
Laidler,  op.  cit.,  242. 

On  the  topic  generally  see  Handler,  Cases  and  Materials  on  Trade  Regulation  (1937)  463  et  seg.;  Hale, 
Trust  Dissolution:  "Atomizing"  Business  Units  of  Monopolistic  Size  (1940).  40  Col.  L.  Rev.  615. 

"  Standard  Oil  Company  of  New  Jersey  v.  United  States  (1911),  221  U.  S.  1,  53. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  g5 

tions  between  the  two  concepts.  As  is  pointed  out  in  the  recent 
Socony-Vacuum  case  ^^  every  monopoly  may  constitute  a  restraint  of 
trade  but  not  every  restraint  of  trade  is  monopoUstic.^^  In  practice, 
the  doctrines  of  restraint  of  trade  have  developed  in  and  have  been 
applied  to  confederations  of  competitors  ^^  whereas  the  monopoly 
concept  has  been  of  principal  importance  in  the  field  of  mergers  and 
consolidations.  Where  competition  is  restrained  by  agreement  or 
understanding  between  ostensibly  independent  competitors,  the  courts 
have  perceived  that  the  public  sustains  injury  notwithstanding  that 
the  conspirators  may  lack  monopoly  power.  Where,  however,  com- 
peting businesses  are  fused  by  merger  or  consolidation,  the  courts 
have  not  regarded  the  consequent  disappearance  of  competition  as 
serious  where  the  new  unit  lacked  at  least  a  semblance  of  monopoly 
power.  Hence,  for  many  years  a  sharp  distinction  in  fact  obtained 
between  the  doctrines  laid  down  in  the  loose-knit  and  merger  cases. 
As  we  have  noted  in  the  section  on  degree  of  market  control,  ^^  prior 
to  the  Appalachian  Coals  case  ^^  it  was  consistently  held  that  the  sup- 
pression of  competition  by  agreement  was  unlawful  regardless  of  the 
market  position  of  the  parties  to  the  agreement.  The  Appalachian 
case  ^-^  not  only  inaugurated  a  new  rule  in  respect  of  loose-knit  con- 
federations, now  somewhat  eclipsed  by  the  recent  Socony-Vacuum  ^^ 
decision,  but  denied  any  difference  between  the  application  of  the 
statute  to  mergers  and  loose-knit  combinations.  Mr.  Chief  Justice 
Hughes  stated: 

*  *  *  We  agree  that  there  is  no  ground  for  holding  defendants'  plan  illegal 
merely  because  they  have  not  integrated  their  properties  and  have  chosen  to 
maintain  their  independent  plants,  seeking  not  to  limit  but  rather  to  facilitate 
production.  We  know  of  no  public  policy,  and  none  is  suggested  by  the  terms 
of  the  Sherman  Act,  that,  in  order  to  comply  with  the  law,  those  engaged  in  indus- 
try should  be  driven  to  unify  their  properties  and  businesses,  in  order  to  correct 
abuses  which  may  be  corrected  by  less  drastic  measures.  Public  policy  might 
indeed  be  deemed  to  point  in  a  different  direction.  *  *  *  The  question  in 
either  case  is  whether  there  is  an  unreasonable  restraint  of  trade  or  an  attempt 
to  monopolize.  If  there  is,  the  combination  cannot  escape  because  it  has  chosen 
corporate  form;  and,  if  there  is  not,  it  is  not  to  be  condemned  because  of  the 
absence  of  corporate  integration.     *     *     *  ^^ 

It  is  arguable  that  the  elimination  of  competition  by  purchase  should 
no  more  be  tolerated  than  its  suppression  by  agreement,  and  that  the 
same  rules  should  govern  both  branches  of  the  anti-trust  laws.  The 
problem,  however,  remains  whether  the  coalescence  should  be  effected 
by  the  adoption  of  the  more  liberal  rule  applicable  to  mergers,  as 
was  suggested  by  the  Court  in  the  Ap>palachian  case,^^  or  of  the  more 
stringent  rule  apphcable  to  restraint  of  trade.  The  recent  Socony- 
Vacuum  case  ^^  appears  to  reinstate  the  distmction  which  the  Appa- 

3»  United  States  v.  Socony-Vacuum  Oil  Co.  (1940),  310  U.  S.  150. 

31  "The  existence  or  exertion  of  power  to  accomplish  the  desired  objective  •  *  *  becomes  important 
only  in  cases  where  the  offense  charged  is  the  actual  monopolizing  of  any  part  of  trade  or  commerce  in  viola- 
tion of  sec.  2  of  the  act.  An  intent  and  a  power  to  produce  the  result  which  the  law  condemns  are  then 
necessary.  *  *  *  But  the  crime  under  sec.  1  is  legally  distinct  from  that  under  sec.  2  *  *  *  though 
the  two  sections  overlap  in  the  sense  that  a  monopoly  under  sec.  2  is  a  species  of  restraint  of  trade  under  sec. 
1.  *  '  *  Only  a  confusion  between  the  nature  of  the  offenses  under  those  two  sections  .*  '  *  would 
lead  to  the  conclusion  that  power  to  fix  prices  was  necessary  for  proof  of  a  price-fixing  conspiracy  under  sec. 
1.     *     *     •"     Id.  226  n.  59. 

32  See  sections  dealing  with  the  loose-knit  confederations,  supra,  p.  XXX  et  seq. 

33  Supra. 

3<  Appalachian  Coals,  Inc.,  v.  United  States  (1933),  288  V.  S.  344. 

35  Ibid. 

36  United  Slates  v.  Socony-Vacuum  Oil  Co.  (1940),  310  U.  S.  150. 

3'  Appalachian  Coals,  Inc.,  v.  United  States  (1933),  288  U.  S.  344.  376. 

38  Id.  at  377. 

3«  United  Stales  v.  Socony-Vacuum  Oil  Co.  (1940),  310  U.  S.  150. 


gg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

lachian  decision  ^^  sought  to  obliterate,  but  a  single  standard  is  still 
possible,  should  the  courts  decide  to  narrow  the  area  of  permissible 
corporate  integration. 

15.    STOCK    ACQUISITIONS    AND    HOLDING    COMPANIES 

Congress  in  the  Clayton  Act  of  1914  "  sought  to  discourage  the 
merger  process  by  curbing  two  of  the  easiest  methods  by  which  com- 
panies may  be  combined.  Section  7  of  the  act  forbids  stock  acquisi- 
tions in  *-  and  holding  company  control  of  *^  competing  companies 
engaged  in  interstate  commerce  where  the  acquisition  has  the  effect 
of  (1)  substantially  lessening  competition  between  such  companies, 
(2)  restraining  commerce  in  any  section  or  community,  or  (3)  creating 
or  tending  to  create  a  monopoly  in  any  line  of  commerce. 

Although  the  first  of  the  statutory  standards  was  an  innovation  in 
the  antitrust  field,  the  second  and  third  were  essentially  the  same  as 
those  prescribed  by  the  Sherman  Act.  Precisely  what  was  intended 
by  the  first  standard  is  not  easy  of  determination.  Since  the  acquisi- 
tion of  a  controlling  interest  in  two  competing  corporations  for  non- 
investment  purposes  *■*  cannot  fail  to  eliminate  competition  between 
them,  it  is  difficult  to  understand  what  is  meant  by  the  qualifying 
expression  "substantially  lessen  competition  between  the  corporation 
whose  stock  is  so  acquired  and  the  corporation  making  the  acquisi- 
tion." The  plu'aseology  implies  that  there  may  be  some  acquisitions 
which  may  not  lessen  competition  substantially  and  which  are  there- 
fore lawful.  Yet  it  is  difficult  to  envisage  a  case  where  such  purchases 
would  not  fail  to  eliminate  competition  entirely,  notwithstanding 
that  the  controlled  company  might  be  operated  as  an  ostensible 
competitor.  If  Congress  merely  desired  by  this  language  to  permit 
the  combination  of  non-competing  companies,  its  intention  could 
evidently  have  been  more  directly  expressed.  Similarly,  if  it  intended 
to  prohibit  all  acquisitions  of  a  controlling  interest  in  competitive 
corporations,  a  more  explicit  interdiction  would  have  avoided  the 
frustrating  construction  of  the  courts. 

The  judicial  interpretation  of  section  7  has  deprived  it  of  most  of  its 
intended  effect.  The  courts  have  held  that  for  the  statute  to  be 
applicable  the  combining  companies  must  have  been  in  substantial 
competition  with  each  other  prior  to  their  union.^^  The  cases  have 
also  indicated  that  an  acquisition  is  not  to  be  condemned  merely 
because  it  diminishes  competition  between  the  two  companies  involved 
in  the  transaction;  it  must  also  be  shown  that  competition  in  the  in- 
dustry at  large  has  been  substantially  aft'ected.^^  In  other  words, 
there  is  a  tendency  to  erase  the  first  of  the  statutory  standards  of 
legality,  or  stated  differently,  to  amalgamate  it  with  the  familiar 
standards  of  the  Sherman  law. 

i"  Appalachian  Coals,  Inc.,  v.  United  Slates  (1933),  288  U.  S.  344. 

<i  3«  Stat.  730  (1914),  15  U.  S.  C.  sec.  12. 

<2  38  Stat.  731  (19H),  15  U.  S.  C.  sec.  18. 

«38  Stat.  732  (1914),  15  U.  S.  C.  sec.  18. 

"  There  is  a  specific  exemption  from  the  condemnation  of  the  act  where  corporations  purchase  stock  for 
investment  piir|)oses  only,  and  the  stock  is  not  used  to  bring  about  thesubstantiallessening  of  competition. 
38  Stat.  732  (1914),  15  U.  S.  C.  sec.  18. 

"  International  Shoe  Company  v.  Federal  Trade  Commission  (1930),  280  U.  S.  291;  Temple  Anthracite  Coal 
Company  v.  Federal  Trade  Commission  (C.  C.  A.  3d,  1931),  51  F.  (2d)  656;  V.  Vivaudou,Inc.,v.  Federal  Trade 
Commission  (C.  C.  A.  2d,  1931),  54  F.  (2d)  273. 

"  Temple  Anthracite  Coal  Company  v.  Federal  Trade  Commission  (C.  C.  A.  3d,  1931),  51  F.  (2d)  656;  V. 
Vivaudou,  Inc.,  v.  Federal  Trade  Commission  (C.  C.  A.  2d,  1931),  54  F.  {2d)  273. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  §7 

The  Federal  Trade  Commission  is  authorized  by  section  1 1  to  issue 
orders  compelling  persons  subject  to  the  act  to  cease  and  desist  from 
such  violations  and  to  divest  themselves  of  stock  acquired  in  contra- 
vention of  the  statute.*^ 

Under  this  section  as  interpreted  by  the  courts  the  Commission 
may  order  the  divestiture  of  stock  only  if  the  wrongfully  acquired 
stock  is  held  by  the  respondent  at  the  time  its  order  is  promulgated. 
The  Commission  is  ousted  of  jurisdiction  if  the  respondent  exchanges 
the  stock  for  the  assets  of  the  acquired  company  either  before  *^  or 
after  ^^  the  issuance  of  the  Commission's  complaint  but  before  the 
issuance  of  the  cease  and  desist  order. ■*^*  Thus,  by  using  the  wrong- 
fully acquired  secm'ities  to  consummate  the  corporate  integration 
which  was  initiated  by  a  stock  acquisition  or  holding  company,  the 
respondent  can  defeat  the  Commission's  jurisdiction  and  the  trans- 
action  can   only   be   assailed   in   a   plenary   action   in   the   courts. ^^ 

The  Federal  Trade  Commission  has  repeatedly  advocated  amend- 
ment of  section  7  and  has  described  at  length  the  adverse  conditions 
under  which  it  operates  in  the  enforcement  of  this  section.^^  It 
offered  considerable  testimony  to  this  committee  concerning  the 
difficulties  confronted  in  the  administration  of  this  section  and  it  has 
presented  at  length  its  suggestions  for  legislative  change. ^^ 

The  need  for  legislative  amendment  of  section  7  is  apparent.  It  is 
clear  that  the  present  limitations  on  the  Commission's  power  of 
enforcement  should  be  removed.  The  Commission's  jurisdiction 
should  not  end  with  the  surrender  of  the  wrongfully  acquired  stock 
for  the  physical  assets  and  property  of  the  acquired  company.  It 
should  be  given  the  power  to  proceed  against  persons  who  have 
violated  the  statute  even  though  they  no  longer  retain  the  illegally 
acquu'ed  stock.  Moreover,  since  section  7  subjects  the  acquisition  of 
stock  and  holding  company  control  to  the  administrative  regulation 
of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  it  is  diffi,cult  to  perceive  why  the 

<'  38  Stat.  734  (1914),  15  U.  S.  C.  sec.  21.  Authority  to  enforce  compliance  with  the  act  is  vested  in  the 
"Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  where  applicable  to  common  carriers  *  *  *  in  the  Federal  Com- 
munications Commission,  where  applicable  to  common  carriers  engaged  in  wire  or  radio  communication 
*  *  *,  in  the  Board  of  Governors  of  the  Federal  Reserve  System,  where  applicable  to  banks,  banking  asso- 
ciations, and  trust  companies;  and  in  the  Federal  Trade  Comndssion,  where  applicable  to  all  other  character 
of  commerce,    *    *    *." 

4s  Federal  Trade  Commission  v.  Thatcher  Manufacturing  Company  (C.  C.  A.  3d,  1925),  5  F.  (2d)  615,  modified 
(1920),  272  U.  S.  554:  Swift  &  Company  v.  Federal  Trade  Commission,  (1926),  272  U.  S.  554. 

48a  Federal  Trade  Commission  v.  Thatcher  Manufacturing  Company, {C.  C.  A.  3d,  1925),  5  F.  {Sd)  615,  Modi- 
fled  (1926)  272  U.  S.  554. 

49  Arrow-Hart  &  Hegeman  Electric  Co.  v.  Federal  Trade  Commission,  (1934),  291  U.  S.  587. 

'"  Authority  to  enforce  section  7  is  vested  in  the  Department  of  .Tustice  as  well  as  the  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission. 38  Stat.  736  (1914),  15  U.  S.  C.  sec.  25.  Persons  aga;rieved  by  a  violation  of  this  as  well  as  other 
sections  of  the  Clayton  Act  may  under  section  16  bring  a  private  suit  for  injunction.  38  Stat.  737  (1914), 
15  U.  S.  C.  sec.  26.  There  appears  to  be  no  reported  case  in  which  the  power  of  the  Department  of  Justice 
to  assail  an  acquisition  of  assets  brought  about  by  the  use  of  illegally  acquired  stock  has  been  considered. 
It  is  impossible  to  state  with  any  assurance  whether  a  similar  limitation  is  applicable  in  a  court  proceeding 
brought  by  the  Department  of  Justice. 

"  Hearings  before  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  (1939),  vol.  Ill,  pp.  38  fl.;  vol.  II,  pp. 
262  #.  F.  T.  C.  Annual  Report  (1940)  13.  In  its  Annual  Report  for  1940  the  Federal  Trade  Commission 
renews  its  recommendations  set  forth  in  its  previous  reports.  F.  T.  C,  Annual  Report  (1940)  12.  The 
Annual  Report  for  1939reveals  that  the  changes  sought  by  the  Commission  are  (1)  that  sec.  11  of  the  Clayton 
Act  be  amended  in  order  that  the  Commission  will  have  authority  to  require  a  corporation  to  divest  itself 
of  assets  illegally  acquired;  (2)  that  sec.  7  be  amended  in  order  to  make  it  unlawful  for  any  corporation, 
directly  or  indirectly,  through  a  holding  company,  subsidiary,  or  otherwise,  to  acquire  any  of  the  capital 
stock  or  assets  of  a  competing  corporation  when  either  of  said  corporations  is  engaged  in  interstate  com- 
merce, or  for  a  holding  corporation  to  acquire  any  of  the  capital  stock  or  assets  of  a  single  corporation,  engaged 
in  interstate  commerce,  or  for  a  holding  corporation  to  acquire  any  of  the  caiiital  stock  or  assets  of  a  single 
corparation,  engaged  in  interstate  commerce  in  competition  with  a  subsidiary  of  the  holiiing  corporation 
when  the  effect  of  such  acquisition  of  stock  or  assets  may  be  substantially  to  lessen  competition  between 
the  two  corporations  or,  where,  from  the  relative  size  of  the  corporation  resulting  from  the  merger  and  the 
surrounding  conditions,  the  effect  of  such  acquisition  may  be  to  restrain  competition  or  tend  to  create  a 
monopoly  in  any  line  of  commerce.  F.  T.  C,  Annual  Report  (1939)  14  et  seq.  The  Commission  regards 
as  undesirable,  however,  the  enactment  of  an  inflexible  limit  on  the  permissible  percentage  of  control 
which  a  corporation  can  acquire  in  any  one  industry.    Id.  at  16. 

"Id.  vol.  IV,  p.  643  ff. 


g§  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

acquisition  of  assets  in  competing  companies  should  not  similarly  be 
placed  under  the  Commission's  supervision. 

Such  changes,  however,  do  not  go  to  the  root  of  the  difficulty.  If 
it  be  desired  to  outlaw  the  use  of  the  holding  company  and  the  acqui- 
sition of  stock  as  a  means  of  uniting  competing  companies,  an 
unequivocal  prohibition  is  essential.  Furthermore,  it  will  serve  no 
useful  purpose  to  widen  the  Commission's  authority  over  property 
acquisitions  if  the  substantive  law  governing  their  legality  remains 
untouched. 

For  50  years  we  have  sought  to  curb  undue  concentration  of 
economic  power  by  attacking  capital  combinations  after,  rather  than 
before,  their  formation.  This  has  given  rise  to  the  vexing  problem  of 
"unscrambling  the  eggs,"  and  has  created  a  psychological  barrier  to 
the  vigorous  enforcement  and  the  sound  interpretation  of  the  law. 

We  believe  that  no  combination  of  competing  companies  should  be 
permitted  without  the  advance  approval  of  an  administrative  agency, 
such  as  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  operating  under  a  new  legis- 
lative standard.  In  a  field  such  as  this,  it  is  impossible  to  formulate  a 
standard  which  will  be  free  of  all  uncertainty,  unless  some  inflexible 
limitation  on  the  size  of  corporate  enterprise  or  the  degree  of  per- 
mitted concentration  in  any  industry  is  imposed.  Limitations  on 
corporate  size,  however,  confuse  bigness  with  monopoly.  The 
adoption  of  any  mathematical  standard  in  respect  of  the  permissible 
degree  of  control  of  any  industry  would  strait-jacket  our  economy 
and  would  achieve  certainty  only  at  the  expense  of  that  flexibility 
without  which  the  legal  control  of  economic  life  cannot  succeed. 
More  general  and  less  precise  standards  are  to  be  preferred. 

We  accordingly  recommend  the  enactment  of  legislation — 

(1)  Prohibiting  the  acquisition  of  stock  in  and  holding-com- 
pany control  of  competing  companies,  in  the  case  of  corporations 
of  a  net  worth  of  $1,000,000  or  more,  with  suitable  exceptions 
for  bona  flde  investments  and  the  control  of  true  subsidiaries  by 
parent  corporations; 

(2)  Subjecting  the  acquisition  of  the  assets  and  property  of 
competing  companies  to  administrative  supervision  in  the  case 
of  corporations  with  a  net  worth  of  $5,000,000,  or  more,  no  such 
acquisition  to  be  permitted  without  the  advance  approval  of  the 
Commission.  The  approval  of  a  merger,  consolidation,  or  property 
acquisition  should  only  be  granted  if  the  Commission  finds  after 
investigation  and  hearing — 

(a)  That  the  acquisition  is  in  the  public  interest  and  will  be  pro- 

motive of  greater  efficiency  and  economy  of  production, 
distribution,  and  management; 

(b)  That  it  will  not  substantially  lessen  competition,  restrain 

trade,  or  tend  to  create  a  monopoly  in  the  trade,  industry, 
or  line  of  connnercc  in  which  such  corporations  are 
engaged ; 

(c)  That  the  corporations  involved  in  such  acquisition  do  not 

include  one  or  more  of  the  10  leading  companies  in  the 
trade,  industry,  or  line  of  commerce  in  which  they  are 
engaged  as  determined  by  plant  capacity,  output,  or 
volume  of  sales  of  the  goods  or  services  as  to  which  such 
corporations  compete; 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  89 

(d)  That  the  size  of  the  acquiriiiii;  company  after  the  ac(iiiisitioii 

will  not  be  incompatible  with  the  existence  and  mainte- 
nance of  vigorous  and  effective  competition  in  the  trade, 
industry,  or  line  of  commerce  in  which  it  is  engaged; 

(e)  That  the  acquisition  will  not  so  reduce  the  number  of  com- 

peting companies  in  the  trade,  industry,  or  line  of  com- 
merce as  materiall}^  to  lessen  the  effectiveness  and  vigor 
of  competition  in  such  trade,  industry,  or  line  of  com- 
merce; 

(J)  That  the  size,  strength,  and  position  of  the  acquiring  com- 
pany after  the  acquisition  will  not  be  such  as  to  enable  it, 
by  reason  of  its  own  administrative  action,  apart  from 
the  forces  of  competition,  to  fix  and  maintain  the  prices- 
of  the  goods  or  services  which  it  sells; 

(g)  That  the  acquiring  company  has  not,  to  induce  the  acqui- 
sition, indulged  in  any  unfair  or  deceptive  methods  of 
competition  or  has  not  otherwise  violated  the  provisions 
of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act,  as  amended. 

No  merger  should  be  approved  which  does  not  satisfy  all  of  the 
standards.  We  have  been  content  here  to  express  merely  the  prin- 
ciples of  tliis  method  of  regulation;  the  standards  themselves  must  be 
carefully  drafted  so  as  to  be  administrable  and  workable.  The  Com- 
mission should  have  the  power  in  exceptional  cases,  notwithstanding 
noncompliance  with  the  above-enumerated  standards,  to  approve  a 
proposed  corporate  acquisition  where  the  pubHc  interest  so  requires  as 
in  the  case  of  banlo-uptcy  or  threatened  insolvency  or  where  the  com- 
bining companies  are  engaged  in  an  industry  dominated  by  a  larger 
company  and  the  integration  is  designed  to  remove  or  reduce  the 
disparity  of  power  between  the  combining  and  the  dominant  corpo- 
ration. 

To  facilitate  the  administration  of  the  new  law,  a  statutory  pre- 
sumption should  be  adopted  making  any  acquisition  or  fusion  pre- 
sumptively unlawful  when  the  acquiring  company  after  the  acquisi- 
tion will  control  more  than  15  percent  of  either  capacity,  output  or 
volume  of  sales  in  the  trade,  industry,  or  line  of  commerce  in  which 
such  company  is  engaged.  This  presumption  should  be  subject  to 
rebuttal  by  competent  proof  showing  satisfaction  of  the  statutory 
standards. 

Full  judicial  review  should  be  permitted  in  cases  where  adminis- 
trative approval  of  a  contemplated  acquisition  is  withheld. 

These  tentative  proposals  would  (1)  outlaw  the  stock  acquisition 
and  holding  company  as  methods  of  combining  competing  corpora- 
tions without  disturbing  the  legitimate  use  of  the  holding  company 
device  in  the  relations  between  parent  and  subsidiary  companies, 
(2)  strengthen  the  administrative  authority  of  the  agencies  entrusted 
with  the  administration  of  the  new  law  thus  avoiding  the  vexatious 
limitations  upon  the  powers  of  enforcement  of  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission,  (3)  would  clarify  to  a  degree  the  substantive  standards 
governing  the  legality  of  the  combinations  of  competitors,  (4)  would 
employ  the  administrative  rather  than  the  judiciary  in  the  initial 
application  of  standards  which  are  as  much  economic  as  legal,  and 
(5)  would  substitute  prevention  for  punishment  by  requiring  approval 

291144— 41— No.  38 7 


90  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

in  advance  of  any  integration  rather  than  compulsory  dissolution 
after  the  evils  of  concentration  have  been  suffered  by  the  public. 

ANTITRUST  ENFORCEMENT 

As  part  of  our  examination  of  the  antitrust  laws  and  their  enforce- 
ment we  studied  the  procedural  and  administrative  aspects  of  these 
laws  as  well  as  their  substantive  content.  These  phases  of  the 
antitrust  laws  were  simultaneously  surveyed  by  Professor  Walton 
Hamilton  and  Miss  Irene  Till.  As  their  report,  entitled  "Anti- 
Trust  Laws  in  Action,"  has  been  already  filed  with  this  Committee, 
so,  we  shall,  to  avoid  repetition,  merely  confine  our  consideration  of 
this  topic  to  a  statement  of  our  conclusions,  without  setting  forth 
the  factual  data  upon  which  they  are  based. 

We  find  that  the  basic  wealaiesses  in  antitrust  enforcement  derive 
from  (a)  the  inadequacy  of  appropriations  and  personnel;  (b)  the 
complexity  of  antitrust  litigation  and  the  inadequacies  of  procedure; 
and  (c)  the  inadequacy  of  existing  penalties  and  remedies. 

A.    THE  INADEQUACY  OF  APPROPRIATIONS  AND  PERSONNEL 

No  matter  how  perfect  the  substantive  law  may  be  and  how  effi- 
cient and  streamlined  the  machinery  for  enforcement,  effective  enforce- 
ment is  impossible  without  adequate  funds  and  personnel.  On  the 
other  hand,  adequate  personnel,  well  supplied  with  funds,  can  achieve 
marked  success  in  the  enforcement  of  any  statute,  notwithstanding 
serious  procedural  and  substantive  defects.  The  point,  therefore, 
cannot  be  reiterated  too  emphatically  that  improvement  of  the  enforce- 
ment of  our  antitrust  laws  is  dependent  primarily  upon  larger  appro- 
priations and  a  larger  and  better-rounded  enforcement  staff.  There 
has  been  a  considerable  expansion  of  the  Antitrust  Division  during 
recent  years.  Neither  appropriations  nor  personnel  are  as  yet  ade- 
quate for  the  enormous  tasks  of  antitrust  enforcement.  The  objec- 
tives of  our  antitrust  policy  can  only  be  achieved  through  continuous, 
systematic  and  efficient  enforcement  of  the  laws.  To  tolerate  wrong- 
doing by  r(^ason  of  a  paucity  of  money  and  manpower  is  to  sanction 
the  discriminatory  and  uneven  administration  of  the  law. 

B.    COMPLEXITY    OF    ANTITRUST    LITIGATION  AND  THE  INADEQUACIES  OF 

PROCEDURE 

Antitrust  suits  are  of  enormous  complexity  and  the  procedures  suit- 
able for  ordinary  litigation  have  frequently  proved  inadequate. 

1 .  To  ascertain  whether  a  breach  of  the  law  has  occurred  the  Gov- 
ernment has  customarily  relied  for  the  most  part  on  the  complaints  of 
those  adversely  afl'ected  by  the  violation.  However  satisfactoiy  such 
a  jjrocedurc  may  be  in  other  fields,  the  restriction  of  investigation  to 
sucli  ('onii)la.ints  as  are  received  may  have  the  effect  of  granting  a  tem- 
porary innnunity  to  industries  in  which  restrictive  practices  have 
become  the  established  ovdor  and  are  thus  not  the  subject  of  objection. 
An  industry,  skilled  in  the  ways  of  evasion  and  violation,  may  thus  for 
long  periods  of  time  violate  the  law  with  impunity.  A  suitable  ma- 
chinery for  the  detection  of  violations  must  be  created  if  the  statute  is 
to  be  enforced  not  merely  against  the  flagrant  violation  which  gives 
rise  to  complaint,  but  the  secret  transgression  which  may  insidiously 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  Q^ 

impair  our  competitive  institutions.  A  valuable  start  in  this  dir(>ction 
has  been  made  by  the  recently  adopt(Hl  project  method  of  enforce- 
ment, as  in  the  drive  against  the  restrictive  practices  in  the  building 
industries.  A  systematic  attack  upon  the  practices  of  an  entire 
industry  or  concentration  upon  certain  well-defined  practices  infesting 
all  of  industry  is  more  fruitful  than  the  hit-and-miss  prosecution  of  the 
sporadic  and  unrelated  complaints  of  miscellaneous  practices  in 
various  industries.  Adequate  machinery  of  detection  is  essential  to 
any  well-rounded  and  coherent  program  of  enforcement. 

2.  The  processes  of  investigation  are  unduly  cumbersome.  Access 
to  the  books  and  records  of  corporations  under  investigation  can  be  had 
only  with  the  consent  of  such  companies  or  by  convening  a  grand  jury. 
To  summon  a  grand  jury  in  the  initial  stages  of  an  investigation  may  be 
tactically  unwise  and  may  involve  elements  of  unfairness  to  the 
persons  under  investigation.  The  grand  jury  is  a  ponderous  and  costly 
institution,  which  is  ill-teuited  for  the  usual  preliminary  ascertainment 
of  possible  wrongdoing.  More  efficient  machinery  can  undoubtedly  be 
constructed  for  preliminary  investigation,  reserving  the  grand  jury  for 
the  difficult  and  important  inquiries  for  which  its  historic  processes 
are  better  adapted. 

3.  Under  the  decisions  of  the  Supreme  Court,  each  case  is  virtually 
a  law  unto  itself  and  the  unreasonableness  of  a  restraint  or  practice 
must  be  shown  in  terms  of  the  facts  and  conditions  of  the  industry  in 
which  they  occur.  There  must  be  proof  that  the  conduct  under  ques- 
tion in  tendency  or  effect  is  restrictive  of  competition  and  that  the 
restraint  in  terms  of  the  facts  of  the  particular  industry  is  unreason- 
able. The  items  of  proof  which  the  Court  regards  material  are  indi- 
cated in  the  followmg  passage  from  the  opinion  of  Mr.  Justice  Brandeis 
in  Board  of  Trade  of  the  City  of  Chicago  v.  United  States:  ^^ 

*  *  *  But  the  legality  of  an  agreement  or  regulation  cannot  be  determined 
by  so  simple  a  test,  as  whether  it  restrains  competition.  Every  agreement  con- 
cerning trade,  every  regulation  of  trade,  restrains.  To  bind,  to  restrain,  is  of 
their  very  essence.  The  true  test  of  legality  is  whether  the  restraint  imposed  is 
such  as  merely  regulates  and  perhaps  thereby  promotes  competition  or  whether 
it  is  such  as  may  suppress  or  even  destroy  competition.  To  determine  that  ques- 
tion the  court  must  ordinarily  consider  the  facts  peculiar  to  the  business  to  which 
the  restraint  is  applied;  its  condition  before  and  after  the  restraint  was  imposed; 
the  nature  of  the  restraint  and  its  effect,  actXial  or  probable.  The  history  of  the 
restraint,  the  evil  believed  to  exist,  the  reason  for  adopting  the  particular  remedy, 
the  purpose  or  end  sought  to  be  attained,  are  all  relevant  facts.  This  is  not  be- 
cause a  good  intention  will  save  an  otherw/ise  objectionable  regulation  or  the 
reverse;  but  because  knowledge  of  intent  may  help  the  court  to  interpret  facts 
and  to  predict  consequences.     *     *     =)= 

The  collection  of  all  this  background  information  is  attended  with 
much  difficulty  and  is  very  costly  of  time,  manpower,  and  money. 
The  burden  of  assembling  such  material  is  very  considerable  and  the 
preparation  of  an  antitrust  case  for  trial  presents  problems  which  are 
virtually  sui  generis. 

4.  The  ordinary  processes  of  litigation  are  ill-adapted  to  the  trial 
and  determination  of  economic  questions.  In  addition  to  the  fact 
that  there  exist  teclmical  rules  which  complicate  and  make  expensive 
the  proof  of  facts  which  are  indisputable,  it  is  no  easy  feat  to  conform 
the  difficult  economic  inquiries  involved  in  antitrust  litigation  to  the 
rules  of  evidence  and  procedm-e  which  the  common  law  developed  for 
the  trial  of  simple  issues  of  law  and  fact.     In  the  International  liar- 

"(1918),  246  U.  S.  231,238. 


92  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

vester  case,  ^^  for  example,  the  Government  offered  in  evidence  and 
relied  upon  a  study  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  dealing  with  the 
competitive  conditions  in  the  agricultural  machinery  industry.  The 
Supreme  Court  reproached  the  Government  for  its  reliance  upon  the 
report  of  the  Federal  Trade  Com.mission  in  the  following  terms: 

*  *  *  the  Government  relies  in  large  measure  upon  various  statements  and 
tabulations  contained  in  the  report  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  which  was 
introduced  in  evidence  over  the  objection  of  the  International  Co.  But  it  is 
entirely  plain  that  to  treat  the  statements  in  this  report — based  upon  an  ex  parte 
investigation  and  formulated  in  the  manner  hereinabove  set  forth — as  constitut- 
ing in  themselves  substantive  evidence  upon  the  questions  of  fact  here  mvolved, 
violates  the  fundamental  rules  of  evidence  entitling  the  parties  to  a  trial  of  issues 
of  fact,  not  upon  hearsay,  but  upon  the  testimony  of  persons  having  first  hand 
knowledge  of  the  facts,  who  are  produced  as  witnesses  and  are  subject  to  the  test 
of  cross-examination.     *     *     *  55 

5.  The  cost  of  antitrust  litigation  to  the  Government  and  the  de- 
fendants is  notoriously  large.  With  the  cost  of  cases  to  the  Govern- 
ment ranging  from  $100,000  to  $150,000,  the  number  of  suits  that 
may  be  instituted  in  any  one  year  is  necessarily  limited  and  would 
continue  to  be  limited  even  were  Congress  to  double,  treble,  or  quad- 
ruple current  appropriations. 

6.  To  redress  a  violation  of  the  antitrust  laws  frequently  requires 
considerable  changes  in  the  organization  and  structure  of  an  industry 
or  of  the  businesses  involved  in  the  violation.  In  capital  combina- 
tions, the  constituent  units  of  a  combine  have  usually  been  completely 
merged  and  their  identities  lost.  In  trade  association  cases,  the  prac- 
tices assailed  have  become  part  of  the  fabric  of  the  industr}^  and  any 
modification  is  fraught  with  serious  economic  consequence.  Enforce- 
ment involves,  therefore,  not  merely  punislnnent  for  past  derelictions 
and  restraints  upon  future  violations  but  a  reorganization  of  a  business 
or  industry  to  bring  about  a  condition  in  harmony  with  the  law. 
Too  much  emphasis  is  placed  upon  punishment  and  too  little  upon 
prevention. 

C.    RECOMMENDATIONS 

These  difficulties  can  only  be  overcome  by  a  simplification  of  the 
processes  of  antitrust  enforcement,  by  the  discouragement  of  violation 
through  effective  implementation  of  the  statute,  and  by  the  develop- 
ment of  new  procedures  which  will  achieve  the  objectives  of  the  anti- 
trust laws  through  their  own  automatic  operation  rather  than  through 
cumbersome  regulation,  or  widespread  prosecution,  or  litigation. 

We  accordingly  recommend  the  following  changes  in  antitrust  law 
and  procedure: 

I.  Registration  of  trade  groups. — A  trade  association  is  a  public  in- 
stitution. It  may  be  a  powerful  agency  for  good  or  for  evil.  Unlike 
a  private  business  concern  which  may  have  a  definite  interest  in  keep- 
ing secret  its  production  methods  and  marketing  strategy,  a  trade 
association  when  acting  in  th(»  public  interest  should  have  nothing  to 
hide  or  keep  secret.  Its  operation  should  be  completely  in  the  open. 
Perhaps  Adam  Smith  exaggerates  when  he  says: 

*  *  *  people  of  the  same  trade  seldom  meet  together  even  for  merriment 
and  diversion  but  the  conversation  ends  in  a  conspiracy  against  the  public  or  in 
some  contrivance  to  raise  prices, ^^ 

««(1927),274U.  S.  693. 

»*  Id.  at  703. 

"Smith.  Wealth  of  Nations  (Ed.  Caiman)  I,  130. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  93 

but  there  is  alwaj'^s  a  danger  when  peoi)le  of  the  same  trade  get  to- 
gether that  competition  may  be  compromised.  This  danger  can  be 
obviated  in  part  at  least  if  associations  function  openly.  We  pro])ose 
the  enactment  of  legislation  requiring  every  trade  association  to 
register  with  an  agency  of  government  and  to  file  a  registration 
statement  in  such  form  as  the  agency  may  by  rules  and  regula- 
tions prescribe  as  necessary  or  appropriate  in  the  public  interest,  con- 
taming  information  concerning  the  nature  of  the  association ;  the  trade, 
industrj',  or  line  of  commerce  in  which  its  members  are  engaged ;  the 
date  and  place  of  its  formation;  its  purposes  and  objectives;  the  nature 
and  scope  of  the  activities  in  which  it  has  engaged  or  proposes  to 
engage;  and  a  list  of  its  officers  and  members.  With  the  registration 
statement  there  should  also  be  filed  a  copy  of  the  charter,  articles 
of  incorporation,  by-laws,  agreement  of  association,  code  of  ethics, 
and  all  other  papers  and  documents  concerning  the  establishment  and 
organization  of  such  association.  Every  association  in  addition 
should  be  required  to  file  with  the  agency,  in  such  form  and  at 
such  times  as  the  agency  may  by  rules  ancl  regulations  require  as 
necessary  or  appropriate  in  the  public  interest,  but  not  more  often 
than  twice  a  year,  a  report  of  all  of  its  activities  covered  by  such 
report.  These  reports  should  be  accompanied  by  an  affidavit  duly 
sworn  to  and  acknowledged  by  all  the  officers,  and  if  there  be  no  such 
officers,  by  all  the  members  of  the  association,  to  the  effect  (a)  that 
such  reports  constitute  a  complete  record  of  all  the  activities  of  the 
association,  (b)  that  there  has  been  no  discussion  at  any  meeting  of 
the  association  of  price  or  production  policies  of  its  members  or  of 
persons  engaged  in  the  same  trade,  industry,  or  line  of  commerce,  and 
(c)  that  no  agreement  or  understanding  concerning  prices,  production, 
or  the  elimination  of  competition  has  been  made  by  the  members  of 
such  association  during  the  period  covered  by  the  report. 

Trade  associations  should  also  be  required  to  keep  a  complete 
stenographic  record  of  their  proceedings  at  all  regular  and  special 
meetings.  The  stenographic  reports  should  be  kept  at  some  accessible 
place  together  with  an  affidavit  duly  sworn  to  by  the  stenographer 
and  the  officers  of  the  association,  to  the  effect  that  such  stenographic 
record  and  the  transcript  thereof  include  all  business  transacted  and 
all  matters  discussed  at  the  meetings  of  the  association.  The  files  of 
the  association  should  be  maintained  at  the  office  of  a  designated 
officer  or  other  convenient  place  and  should  contain  all  correspond- 
ence between  the  association  and  its  members,  transcripts  and  steno- 
graphic records  of  all  meetings  and  all  pertinent  papers,  documents, 
and  other  material  relating  to  the  association  and  its  activities. 
These  files  should  be  available  at  all  reasonable  hours  to  the  agents 
of  the  Government  for  the  purpose  of  inspection  and  the  making  of 
copies.  The  contents  of  the  files  should  be  preserved  for  such  periods 
of  time  as  may  be  prescribed  by  rules  and  regulations  of  the  Gov- 
ernment agency  and  should  not  be  destroyed  without  the  consent  of 
such  agency  in  accordance  with  such  rules  and  regulations  as  it  may 
prescribe.  Heavy  penalties  should  be  imposed  upon  associations, 
their  members  and  officers,  for  the  neglect  and  failure  to  register;  the 
neglect  and  failure  to  file  a  registration  statement;  the  neglect  and 
failure  to  file  a  report  of  its  activities;  for  willful  misstatements;  for 
false  or  incomplete  entries  in  any  report,  record,  or  affidavit;  for  the 
neglect  or  failure  to  make  or  cause  to  be  made  complete,  true,  and 


g^  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

correct  entries  in  all  reports,  records,  and  affidavits  required  to  be 
filed  or  preserved;  for  the  willful  removal,  destruction,  mutilation,  or 
alteration  of  any  report  or  record;  and  finally,  for  the  refusal  to  per- 
mit the  agents  of  the  Government  to  inspect  and  make  copies  of  the 
contents  of  the  trade  association  files. 

This  proposal  is  not  designed  or  expected  to  be  a  cure-all.     Its 
desirable  effects,  however,  may  be  biiefiy  summarized: 

1.  The  proof  of  background  facts  in  antitrust  litigation  woidd 
be  facilitated  by  the  use  of  the  registration  statements  and  the 
filed  reports.  Access  to  such  statements  and  reports  would  to 
some  extent  reduce  the  expense  and  obviate  the  present  difficulty 
of  collecting  background  data. 

2.  By  requiring  the  maintenance  of  complete  files  by  associa- 
tions at  some  convenient  place  and  making  the  files  accessible 
to  the  Government,  preliminary  investigations  would  be  greatly 
expedited. 

3.  The  requirement  for  open  business  covenants  openly  arrived 
at  would  undoubtedly  drive  collusive  restraints  underground. 
This  is  not  an  unmixed  evil.  The  ordinary  businessman  is  a 
law-abiding  person  and  is  not  disposed  to  participate  in  a  willful 
infraction  of  the  law.  It  is  not  improbable  that  some  business- 
men have  been  induced  to  embark  on  questionable  associational 
programs  under  a  misapprehension  of  their  legality  or  on  the  as- 
sumption that  the  Government,  engaged  in  a  few  major  litiga- 
tions, would  be  too  preoccupied  to  challenge  the  program.  If 
an  association  engages  in  unlawful  conduct  and  files  a  complete 
report  of  its  activities,  detection  no  longer  is  a  problem,  and 
proof  of  violation  is  a  simple  task.  If  the  association  secretly 
engages  in  unlawful  activities  and  fails  to  make  a  full  report,  it 
cannot  keep  this  fact  from  its  members.  It  is  our  beliel  that  a 
very  high  percentage  of  American  businessmen  will  have  nothing 
to  do  with  a  hush-hush  policy  of  secret  violation.  We  regard 
as  a  definite  likelihood  the  withdrawal  of  responsible  and  respect- 
able men  of  business  from  associations  that  fail  to  fulfill  the 
requirements  of  law  with  regard  to  the  accuracy  and  completeness 
of  their  reports.  By  driving  the  illicit  associations  beyond  the 
pale  01  respectability,  we  deprive  them  of  the  suppoit  of  the 
respectable  members  of  the  business  community.  We  therefore 
force  them  either  to  remain  within  the  bounds  of  law  or  to  be- 
come outlaw  organizations.  Juries  would  be  much  less  loath  to 
convict  organizations  operating  underground  in  violation  of  law 
than  they  are  today  to  return  a  verdict  of  guilty  against  an  asso- 
ciation which  openly  has  engaged  in  activities  of  dubious  legality 
under  the  antitrust  laws. 

4.  This  proposal  simplifies  the  litigable  issues  of  fact  and  law. 
Under  present  procedure,  when  the  Government  has  reason  to 
believe  tliat  persons  engai?:od  in  the  same  industry  or  trade  have 
engaged  in  concerted  acts  affecting  competition,  it  must  prove 
both  the  commission  of  the  alleged  acts  as  well  as  that  such  acts 
constitute  in  law  and  fact  an  unreasonable  restraint  of  trade. 
Under  the  proposal,  where  the  reports  and  files  fully  disclose  the 
arrangements  made,  no  time  need  be  wasted  on  proving  what  the 
associat'on  actually  has  done,  the  only  litigable  issue  beuig  the 
legality  of  such  conduct.     If,  however,  the  record  is  incomplete, 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  95 

the  Government  need  merely  show  the  incompleteness,  thus 
proving  a  violation  of  the  proposed  amendment,  without  embark- 
ing on  the  complicated  task  of  proving  that  the  defendants  liave 
engaged  in  an  unlawful  restraint  of  trade. 

5.  As  the  periodic  reports  will  disclose  the  initiation  of  any 
concerted  activity,  the  Government  can  take  action  promptly 
before  the  activity  has  become  the  established  practice  of  the 
industry,  thus  avoiding  the  difficulties  of  disrupting  industry  by 
compelling  the  abandonment  of  usages  that  have  become  firmly 
entrenched. 

6.  As  the  issue  in  trade  association  cnses  becomes  simplified, 
the  cost  of  litigation  should  be  materiall}^  reduced.  It  obviously 
is  much  less  expensive  to  prove  a  failure  to  file  a  report  or  the 
filing  of  an  incomplete  report  than  it  is  to  prove  an  unreasonable 
restraint  of  trade. 

The  proposal,  however,  is  not  without  its  difficulties.  The  defini- 
tion of  the  trade  association  which  is  adopted  will  naturally  determine 
the  scope  of  the  proposal.  If  limited  to  formal  associations,  the  new 
legislation  might  result  in  the  transformation  of  formally  organized 
associations  into  informal  groups.  We,  therefore,  recommend  that  the 
concept  of  the  trade  association  be  broadened  to  include  any  group, 
whether  or  not  incorporated  or  otherwise  formally  organized,  of 
three  or  more  persons  engaged  in  the  same  trade,  industry,  or  line  of 
commerce,  which  is  concerned  with  or  engages  in  concerted  activities 
affecting  the  conduct  and  operation  of  business  in  such  trade,  industry, 
or  line  of  commerce.  In  other  words,  we  believe  tliat  any  arrange- 
ment among  persons  engaged  in  the  same  business  is  affected  with  a 
public  interest  and  should  be  disclosed  to  the  public.  It  will  also  be 
uecessarj'^  to  provide  for  access  to  all  conmiunications  between  com- 
petitors, in  the  cases  where  there  is  no  organization,  formal  or  informal. 

The  requirement  of  periodic  reports  does  not  appear  to  impose  an 
undue  burden  upon  trade  groups.  Engaging  in  concerted  action 
is  a  privilege  which  government  can  extend  or  withhold  from  business. 
The  preparation  of  the  registration  statement  would  not  be  unduly 
difficult.  The  information  which  tiie  Government  might  demand  is 
information  which  the  association  must  assemble,  if  it  is  to  function 
properly.  Requiring  all  communications  to  and  from  the  association 
and  its  members,  as  weU  as  all  communications  among  tiie  members, 
to  be  reduced  to  writing  and  preserved  for  reasonable  periods  of  time 
is  frankly  a  burdensome  requirement,  but  one  which  can  be  fulfilled 
without  serious  effort  or  cost.  Undoubtedly,  associations  and  their 
advisers  might  be  perplexed  by  the  practical  problems  of  inclusion 
and  exclusion.  Transcripts  and  records  would  become  very  bulky 
if  they  included  everything  said  and  done  no  matter  how  inconse- 
quential. The  problem  could  undoubtedly  be  solved  by  the  promul- 
gation of  rules  and  regulations  by  the  administrative  agency,  but  in 
order  that  there  should  be  no  evasion  of  the  purposes  of  the  legislation 
it  would  be  essential  that  tlie  requirement  of  completeness  be  rigor- 
ously applied. 

II.  Declaratory  rulings  and  legality  oj  capital  combinations.- — One 
of  the  principal  difficulties  in  the  application  of  the  statute  to  capital 
combinations  derives  from  the  fact  that  litigation  is  carried  on  after 
rather  than  before  the  event.  This  is  only  essential  if  the  legality 
of  a  capital  combination  is  made  dependent  upon  the  manner  in  which 


gg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

it  wields  the  power  it  possesses  rather  than  upon  the  mere  existence 
of  power.  Since  it  is  possible  to  adopt  a  clearer  criterion  of  the 
legality  of  capital  combinations,  it  would  seem  desu-able  for  the 
validity  of  such  combinations  to  be  determined  in  advance  rather 
than  after  their  formation.  It  requii'es  no  expatiation  to  make  the 
point  that  such  procedm'e  for  advance  approval  would  solve  the 
present  difficulties  of  detection,  collection  of  background  data,  inade- 
quate machinery  for  preliminary  investigation,  "unscrambling  the 
eggs,"  and  cost  of  litigation.  We  have  accordingly  recommended  in 
a  previous  section  "  the  adoption  of  new  standards  and  new  procedure 
for  the  advance  approval  and  determination  of  the  legality  of  corporate 
integrations. 

III.  O'pen  comjprehensive  and  complete  Jiles  on  major  industries. — It 
is  improbable  that  any  substantial  progress  will  be  made  in  the  enforce- 
ment of  the  anti-trust  laws  and  the  regulation  of  industry  until  we 
maintain  open,  comprehensive,  and  complete  files  of  all  oiu-  major 
industries.  One  of  the  primary  tasks  of  the  Bureau  of  Industrial 
Economics  advocated  by  President  Roosevelt  should  be  the  mainte- 
nance of  such  files.  An  extraordinary  amount  of  information  con- 
cerning industry  is  contained  in  the  records  of  numerous  Government 
agencies.  The  task  at  hand  is  essentially  one  of  coordination.  These 
files  could  be  kept  up  to  date  by  a  vigorous  enforcement  as  well  as 
slight  broadening  of  section  6  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act, 
which  requires  corporations  engaged  in  commerce  to  make  regular 
and  periodic  reports  to  the  Commission  with  regard  to  various  aspects 
of  their  business  activity. 

The  device  of  Federal  licensing  affords  a  useful  method  for  collecting 
information  regarding  modern  business,  which  it  should  be  the  duty 
of  the  Government  to  assemble,  analyze,  and  coordinate.  The  exist- 
ence of  such  files  would  materially  lighten  the  burden  of  anti-trust 
litigation,  as  there  would  be  available  to  the  Government  a  good  deal 
of  the  background  data  which  today  is  collected  only  with  much  labor. 
Kjiowledge  is  essential  to  fair  enforcement  and  wise  regulation. 

IV.  Specification  of  ojfenses. — President  Wilson  in  his  message  in 
1914  recommended  an  item-by-item  definition  of  the  offenses  pro- 
hibited by  the  anti-trust  laws.  Apart  from  the  specific  prohibition 
of  a  few  practices  in  the  Clayton  Act,  this  recommendation  was  not 
adopted  by  Congress.  Codification  is  generally  opposed  on  two 
grounds.  It  is  opposed  for  its  alleged  straight-jacketing  effect.  In 
explaining  why  Congress  in  1914  had  adopted  in  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission  Act  the  general  standard  of  unfair  methods  of  com- 
petition rather  than  a  specific  prohibition  of  enumerated  offenses, 
Mr.  Justice  Brandeis  gave  eloquent  expression  to  this  view: 

Instead  of  undertaking  to  define  what  practices  should  be  deemed  unfair,  as 
had  been  done  in  earher  legislation,  the  act  left  the  determination  to  the  Com- 
mission. Experience  with  existing  laws  had  taught  that  definition,  being  neces- 
sarily rigid,  would  prove  embarrassing  and,  if  rigorously  applied,  inight  involve 
grcot  hardship.  Methods  of  competition  which  would  be  luifair  in  one  industry, 
under  certain  circumstances,  might,  when  adopted  in  another  industry,  or  even 
in  the  same  industry  under  diflferent  circumstances,  be  entirely  unobjectionable. 
Furthermore,  an  enumeration,  however  comprehensive,  of  existing  methods  of  un- 
fair competition  must  necessarily  soon  prove  incomplete,  as  with  new  conditions  con- 
stantly arising  novel  unfair  methods  would  be  devised  and  developed.      *      *     *  m 

"  See  supni,  p.  88. 

"  Federal  Trade  Commission  v.  Oratz  (1920),  253  U.  S.  421,  436. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  97 

It  is  froqiiontly  assumed  that  thoro  is  an  irrcconcilabli>  conflict 
bctwooii  the  c:('neral  and  the  specific.  If  choice  had  to  be  made 
between  the  specific  antl  the  2:eneral,  the  general  i)rohibition  is  clearly 
to  be  preferred  because  of  its  flexibility,  adaptability,  and  capacity 
for  discriminatino;  application  as  well  as  o;rowth.  But  there  is  no  such 
irreconcilable  conflict.  There  is  no  reason  why  both  th(>  general  and 
the  specific  cannot  be  employed  in  the  same  legislation.  The  existing 
general  standards  of  the  Sherman  Act  can  be  supplemented  by  specific 
prohibitions  of  oft'enses  which  experience  has  taught  are  fraught  with 
danger  to  our  competitive  institutions.  The  danger  that  the  courts 
might,  under  the  doctrine  of  ejusdem  generis,  construe  the  general 
in  terms  of  the  specific  and  thus  narrow  the  scope  of  the  statute  can 
be  obviated  by  clear,  unequivocal  statutory  language  indicating  the 
legislative  purpose  of  supplementing  rather  than  curtailing  the  general 
provisions  of  the  present  law. 

The  other  objection  to  codification  is  that  clarification  can  best  be 
achieved  through  litigation  of  specific  cases  rather  than  through  any 
generalized  formulation  of  experience  m  the  form  of  legislative  enact- 
ment. If  50  years  of  litigation  under  this  statute  have  failed  to  bring 
clarity  of  meaning  and  scope  to  its  provisions,  what  reason  have  we 
to  believe  that  additional  years  of  litigation  will  be  more  successful 
in  this  regard?  The  Government  publication,  The  Federal  Anti- 
Trust  Laws,  lists  428  cases  instituted  under  the  statute  from  1890 
to  January  1938.  Since  that  time,  many  additional  cases  have  been 
started.  The  Government  Printing  Office  has  published  a  compila- 
tion of  Federal  antitrust  decisions  consisting  of  12  volumes.  This 
compilation  covers  only  the  years  from  1890  to  1931.  About  2  or  3 
additional  volumes  would  probably  be  required  for  the  publication 
of  the  opinions  rendered  smce  1931,  Is  it  at  all  likely  that  further 
litigation  will  achieve  the  clarity  that  has  been  denied  us  by  15  thick 
volumes  of  court  opinions? 

The  time  has  come,  it  is  believed,  for  Congress  to  take  a  hand  in 
the  clarification  of  the  antitrust  laws  and  to  pass  upon  the  difficult 
questions  of  policy  involved  in  the  choice  of  conflicting  doctrine. 
Legislative  codification  and  clarification  would  go  a  long  way  in 
reducing  the  necessity  and  volume  of  litigation  and  would  facilitate 
enforcement  by  the  simplification  of  the  issues  to  be  litigated. 

V.  Implementation  of  the  statute. — The  meffectiveness  of  the 
existing  sanctions  of  our  antitrust  laws  is  notorious. 

The  need  for  increased  penalties  is  widely  recognized.  It  is  im- 
portant, however,  that  the  new  sanctions  be  not  over-severe  since 
excessive  penalties  tend  to  be  self-defeating.  A  penalty  can  be 
sufficiently  stringent  to  serve  as  a  deterrent  without  being  so  severe 
as  to  engender  a  natural  reluctance  on  the  part  of  juries  to  convict  or 
to  arouse  that  antagonism  on  the  part  of  the  courts  which  leads  to  an 
unsympathetic  construction  of  the  substantive  provisions  of  the  law. 

We  believe  it  desirable  to  retain  the  criminal  sanction  as  this  serves 
as  the  principal  deterrent  to  wrongdoing.  We  favor  the  retention 
of  the  equitable  remedies  of  injunction  and  dissolution.  These 
traditional  remedies  should  be  supplemented  by  the  imposition  of 
moderately  severe  civil  penalties  for  wrongdoing. 


9§  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  consent  decree  is  a  useful  device  for  settling  litigation  and  for 
bringing  about  a  condition  in  harmony  with  the  law.^^  We  doubt  the 
wisdom,  however,  of  utilizing  this  device  as  an  instrument  for  the 
affirmative  regulation  of  industry,  for  the  reason  that  there  are  avail- 
able better  and  more  satisfactory  and  more  efficient  instruments  for 
the  administrative  control  of  busmess.  Although  it  frequently  may 
be  necessary  for  the  Government  to  initiate  simultaneously  criminal 
prosecution  to  punish  past  derelictions  and  civU  proceedings  to 
restrain  existing  transgressions,  we  question  whether  the  negotiation 
of  a  consent  decree  lookmg  toward  affirmative  restrictions  in  addition 
to  those  imposed  by  the  antitrust  laws  should  be  undertaken  during 
the  pendency  of  a  grand  jury  investigation.  A  threat  of  criminal 
punishment  is  not  conducive  to  free  negotiation.  However  well  such 
procedures  may  have  operated  in  the  past,  there  is  always  a  danger  that 
the  grand  jury  proceedings  may  be  used  to  compel  the  acceptance  of 
terms  which  otherwise  might  be  resisted.  The  fact  that  such  powers 
may  not  have  been  abused  in  the  past  is  no  guarantee  that  they  may 
not  be  oppressively  wielded  m  the  future.  The  consent  decree  is  an 
efficient  device  for  the  settlement  of  civil  litigation.  Criminal  prosecu- 
tions can  be  terminated  without  tr  al  by  the  filing  of  a  plea  of  guilty 
or  a  plea  of  nolo  contendere.  If  the  violation  is  deservmg  of  the 
institution  of  a  criminal  prosecution  or  the  convening  of  a  grand  jury — 
steps  which  will  themselves  constitute  a  serious  punishment  to  those 
accused  of  wrongdoing — no  discontinuance  of  a  prosecution  should  be 
permitted  without  the  entry  of  either  of  the  aforementioned  pleas. 
The  time  to  negotiate  a  consent  decree  is  before  the  initiation  of  crim- 
inal proceedings,  or  after  their  successful  termination.  The  civil  and 
criminal  suits  should  be  handled  separately,  and  negotiations  for  a 
consent  decree  must  be  conducted  without  any  threat  of  criminal 
prosecution  if  the  negotiations  are  unsuccessful.  The  use  of  the  con- 
sent decree  should  be  limited  to  the  type  of  violation  which  is  typically 
litigated  on  the  civil  side  of  the  court;  violations  which  are  typically 
enforced  by  criminal  prosecution  should  be  settled  by  the  normal 
method  of  a  plea  by  the  defendant. 

Such  restrictions  on  the  use  of  the  consent  decree  might  have  proved 
a  serious  handicap  to  enforcement  officials  when  the  grand  jury  was 
the  only  efficient  instrument  for  the  preliminary  investigation  of 
probable  violations,  especially  when  those  suspected  of  wrongdoing 
refused  the  Government  access  to  their  books  and  papers.  Were  the 
recommended  changes  of  law  and  procedure  adopted,  the  handicaps 
under  which  the  Government  now  operates  would  be  removed,  and 
the  suggestions  concerning  limitations  on  the  use  of  the  consent  decree 
would  consequently  not  unpair  the  fair  and  effective  enforcement  of 
the  law. 

It  is  vital  that  the  profit  be  taken  out  of  antitrust  violations. 
Were  this  possible,  the  principal  incentive  for  wrongdoing  would  be 
removed.  We  suggest,  therefore,  that  consideration  be  given  to  the 
adoption  of  the  ancillary  remedy  of  accounting  m  all  equitable  pro- 
ceedings instituted  by  the  Government.  In  such  accountings  the 
defendants  would  be  required  to  turn  over  all  profits  traceable  to  and 
derived  from  their  unlawful  acts.  The  rules  governmg  such  account- 
ings would  be  similar  to  those  obtainuig  m  trade-mark  and  patent 

'•  For  a  discassion  of  the  use  of  the  consent  decree  see  Isenberg  and  Rubin,  Antitrust  Enforcement  through 
Consent  Decrees  (1940)  53  Uarv.  L.  Rev.  386;  Katz,  Consent  Decree  in  Antitrust  Administration,  id.  at  415. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  99 

litigation.  To  facilitate  the  trial,  a  rebuttable  presumption  might  be 
invoked  to  the  effect  that  all  profits  chiring  the  period  of  violation  in 
excess  of  the  profits  earned  duruig  a  base  period  were  the  product  of 
the  violation,  the  burden  being  shifted  to  the  accounting  party  to  show 
that  such  profits  might  be  attributable  to  other  causes. 

VI.  Distressed  industries. — Excessive  competition  creates  problems 
no  less  serious  than  those  resulting  from  an  absence  of  competition. 
Special  treatment  of  the  distressed  industries  may  be  necessary  if 
they  are  to  function  satisfactorily.  The  nature  and  extent  of  the 
admmistrative  regulation  which  may  be  necessary  will  vary  industry 
by  industry  and  depend  upon  the  causes  of  distress  and  economic 
dislocation.  Any  program  of  legislative  revision  shoukl  make  pro- 
vision for  the  special  treatment  of  our  sick  mdustries. 

VII.  Existing  concentration  in  industry. — The  tightening  of  the  law 
relating  to  capital  combinations  affects  future  corporate  integrations 
but  leaves  untouched  existing  concentrations  of  economic  power.  We 
observed  in  our  review  of  the  judicial  construction  of  section  1  of  the 
Sherman  Act  the  almost  insuperable  difficulty  of  enforcing  the  law  in 
the  concentrated  industries  in  which  competition  is  suppressed  by 
convention  rather  than  by  agreement  or  by  resort  to  secret  devices 
which  are  virtually  incapable  of  detection.  Equally  perplexing  is  the 
application  of  the  monopoly  provisions  of  the  statute  to  those  indus- 
tries in  which  competition  has  either  disappeared  or  remains  weak, 
inert,  or  attenuated.  What  is  to  be  done  with  our  concentrated 
industries? 

A  program  of  vigorous  antitrust  enforcement  may  bring  to  light 
the  secret  arrangements  and  practices  by  which  competition  is  com- 
promised and  might  release  the  potential  forces  of  competition  which 
have  been  long  confined  within  the  bounds  of  industrial  convention 
and  usage.  Such  a  program  would  entail  tremendous  difficulties  of 
detection  and  prosecution.  It  could  succeed  only  to  the  extent  that 
the  absence  or  impairment  of  competition  was  the  result  of  some 
arrangement  prohibited  by  the  antitrust  laws.  To  the  extent  that 
the  noncompetitive  behavior  of  industry  resulted  from  the  fewness 
of  competing  units  or  the  gargantuan  size  or  power  of  the  market 
leader  or  the  established  usages  of  the  industry,  the  enforcement  of 
section  1  of  the  Sherman  law,  no  matter  how  vigorous,  would  not 
restore  competition. 

Competition  in  such  industries  can  be  restored  only  through  a  far- 
reaching  reorganization  of  their  structure.  The  extent  to  which  the 
pulverization  of  industry  is  required  for  the  reestablishment  of  com- 
petitive conditions  is  not  fully  appreciated.  The  atomization  of 
industry  would  cause  serious  economic  dislocation  and  would  seriously 
impede  the  current  defense  program.  The  segregation  of  our  large 
enterprises  into  two  or  tln^ee  component  parts  has  little  beneficial 
short-term  competitive  effects.  The  slight  increase  of  competition 
which  might  result  would  hardly  compensate  for  the  unsettling  effects 
of  such  dissolutions.  This,  however,  is  not  to  deny  the  advantageous 
long-term  effects  of  any  carefully  conceived  and  well-executed  pro- 
gram of  corporate  reorganization. 

We  have  considered  various  proposals  for  invigorating  and  resus- 
citating competition  in  our  concentrated  industries.  We  find  that 
most  of  such  suggestions  are  lacking  in  practical  appeal  or  are  politi- 
cally inexpedient.     Although  one  is  naturally  reluctant  to  suggest 


IQQ  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

further  governmental  regulation  of  industry,  we  see  no  escape  from 
the  conclusion  that  some  administrative  control  of  our  concentrated 
industries  is  essential,  so  long  as,  and  only  as  long  as,  such  industries 
by  their  organization  and  operation  deny  the  public  the  benefits  of 
free  competition.  It  is  only  in  the  case  of  industries  in  which  com- 
petition does  not  function  properly  or  has  disappeared  and  cannot 
be  restored  without  undue  disturbance  of  its  economic  organization 
that  such  administrative  regulation  is  indicated.  The  aim  of  such 
control  would  be  the  attainment,  tlu"Ough  regulation,  of  the  benefits 
normally  flowing  from  a  competitive  regime,  notably  the  constant 
lowering  of  prices  with  a  corresponding  increase  of  production.  Only 
in  this  way  can  the  standards  of  living  be  raised  and  real  income 
enlarged. 

CONCLUSION 

Our  study  of  the  antitrust  laws  and  their  administration  have 
satisfied  us  that  the  objectives  of  these  laws  are  socially  desirable,  are 
economically  sound,  and  are  capable  of  practical  attainment.  With 
increases  of  appropriation  and  personnel,  with  moderate  changes  in 
the  substantive  law,  and  with  some  modifications  of  our  administrative 
procedure,  these  ends  could  be  easily  attained.  The  gains  of  intelli- 
gent, far-sighted,  and  vigorous  enforcement  of  our  antitrust  laws 
greatly  outweigh  the  costs  of  these  recommended  changes. 


a?pp:ndix 
sherman  act  ' 

(U.  S.  C,  Title  15,  Sec.  1) 

AN  ACT  To  protect  trade  and  commerce  against  unlawful  restraints  and  monopolies 

Section  1.  Every  contract,  combination  in  the  form  of  trust  or  otherwise,  or 
conspiracy,  in  restraint  of  trade  or  commerce  among  the  several  States,  or  with 
foreign  nations,  is  hereby  declared  to  be  illegal:  Provided,  That  nothing  herein 
contained  shall  render  illegal,  contracts  or  agreements  prescribing  minimum 
prices  for  the  resale  of  a  commodity  which  bears,  or  the  label  or  container  of 
which  bears,  the  trade-mark,  brand,  or  name  of  the  producer  or  distributor 
of  such  commodity  and  which  is  in  free  and  open  competition  with  commodities 
of  the  same  general  class  produced  or  distributed  by  others,  when  contracts  or 
agreements  of  that  description  are  lawful  as  applied  to  intrastate  transactions, 
under  any  statute,  law,  or  public  policy  now  or  hereafter  in  effect  in  any  State, 
Territory,  or  the  District  of  Columbia  in  which  such  resale  is  to  be  made,  or  to 
which  the  commodity  is  to  be  transported  for  such  resale,  and  the  making  of  such 
contracts  or  agreements  shall  not  be  an  unfair  method  of  competition  under 
section  5,  as  amended  and  supplemented,  of  the  act  entitled  "An  act  to  create  a 
Federal  Trade  Commission,  to  define  its  powers  and  duties,  and  for  other  pur- 
poses," approved  September  26,  1%14::  Provided  further,  That  the  preceding 
proviso  shall  not  make  lawful  any  contract  or  agreement,  providing  for  the  estab- 
lishment or  maintenance  of  minimum  resale  prices  on  any  commodity  herein 
involved,  between  manufacturers,  or  between  producers,  or  between  wholesalers, 
or  between  brokers,  or  between  factors,  or  between  retailers,  or  between  persons, 
firms,  or  corporations  in  competition  with  each  other.  Every  person  w^ho  shall 
make  any  contract  or  engage  in  any  combination  or  conspiracy  hereby  declared 
to  be  illegal  shall  be  deemed  guilty  of  a  misdemeanor,  and,  on  conviction  thereof, 
shall  be  punished  by  fine  not  exceeding  $5,000,  or  by  imprisonment  not  exceeding 
one  year,  or  by  both  said  punishments,  in  the  discretion  of  the  court. 

Sec.  2.  Every  person  who  shall  monopolize,  or  attempt  to  monopolize,  or 
combine  or  conspire  with  any  other  person  or  persons,  to  monopolize  any  part 
of  the  trade  or  commerce  among  the  several  States,  or  with  foreign  nations,  shall 
be  deemed  guilty  of  a  misdemeanor,  and,  on  conviction  thereof,  shall  be  punished 
by  fine  not  exceeding  five  thousand  dollars,  or  by  imprisonment  not  exceeding 
one  year,  or  by  both  said  punishments,  in  the  discretion  of  the  court. 

Sec.  3.  Every  contract,  combination  in  form  of  trust  or  otherwise,  or  conspiracy 
in  restraint  of  trade  or  commerce  in  any  Territory  of  the  United  States  or  of  the 
District  of  Columbia,  or  in  restraint  of  trade  or  commecre  between  any  such 
Territorv  and  another,  or  betw^een  any  such  Territory  or  Territories  and  any 
State  or"  States  or  the  District  of  Columbia,  or  with  foreign  nations,  or  between 
the  District  of  Columbia  and  any  State  or  States  or  foreign  nations,  is  hereby 
declared  illegal.  Every  person  who  shall  make  any  such  contract  or  engage  in 
any  such  combination  or  conspiracy,  shall  be  deemed  guilty  of  a  misdemeanor, 
and,  on  conviction  thereof,  shall  be  punished  by  fine  not  exceeding  five  thousand 
dollars,  or  by  imprisonment  not  exceeding  one  year,  or  by  both  said  punishments, 
in  the  discretion  of  the  court. 

Sec.  4.  The  several  circuit  courts  2  of  the  United  States  are  hereby  invested 
with  jurisdiction  to  prevent  and  restrain  violations  of  this  act;  and  it  shall  be  the 
duty  of  the  several  district  attorneys  of  the  United  States,  in  their  respective 
districts,  under  the  direction  of  the  Attorney  General,  to  institute  proceedings  in 
equity  to  prevent  and  restrain  such  violations.  Such  proceedings  may  be  by 
way  of  petition  setting  forth  the  case  and  praying  that  such  violation  shall  be 

1  Published  as  amended  by  Miller-Tydinfjs  Act  (Public,  No.  314,  75th  Cong.,  H.  R.  7472,  approved  August 
17,  1937).    Seep.  176.  ,        ,      .^  ■ 

2  Act  of  March  3,  1911,  ch.  231,  36  Stat.  1167,  abolishes  the  courts  referred  to,  and  confers  their  powers  upon 
the  district  courts. 

101 


]^Q2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

enjoined  or  otherwise  prohibited.  When  the  parties  complained  of  shall  have 
been  duly  notified  of  such  petition  the  court  shall  proceed,  as  soon  as  may  be,  to 
the  hearing  and  determination  of  the  case,  and  pending  such  petition  and  before 
final  decree,  the  court  may  at  any  time  make  such  temporary  restraining  order  or 
prohibition  as  shall  be  deemed  just  in  the  premises. 

Sec.  5.  Whenever  it  shall  appear  to  the  court  before  which  any  proceeding  un- 
der section  four  of  this  act  may  be  pending,  that  the  ends  of  justice  require  that 
other  parties  should  be  brought  before  the  court,  the  court  may  cause  them 
to  be  summoned,  whether  they  reside  in  the  district  in  which  the  court  is  held 
or  not;  and  subpoenas  to  that  end  may  be  served  in  any  district  by  the  marshal 
thereof. 

Sec.  6.  Any  property  owned  under  any  contract  or  by  any  combination,  or 
pursuant  to  any  conspiracy  (and  being  the  subject  thereof)  mentioned  in  sec- 
tion one  of  this  act,  and  being  in  the  course  of  transportation  from  one  State  to 
another,  or  to  a  foreign  country,  shall  be  forfeited  to  the  United  States,  and 
may  be  seized  and  condemned  by  like  proceedings  as  those  provided  by  law 
for  the  forfeiture,  seizure,  and  condemnation  of  property  imported  into  the 
United  States  contrary  to  law. 

Sec.  7.  Any  person  who  shall  be  injured  in  his  business  or  property  by  any 
other  person  or  corporation  by  reason  of  anything  forbidden  or  declared  to  be 
unlawful  by  this  act,  may  sue  therefor  in  any  circuit  court  of  the  United  States 
in  the  district  in  which  the  defendant  resides  or  is  found,  without  respect  to  the 
amount  in  controversy,  and  shall  recover  threefold  the  damages  by  him  sustained, 
and  the  costs  of  suit,  including  a  reasonable  attorney's  fee. 

Sec.  8.  That  the  word  "person,"  or  "persons,"  wherever  used  in  this  act  shall 
be  deemed  to  include  corporations  and  associations  existing  under  or  authorized 
by  the  laws  of  either  the  United  States,  the  laws  of  any  of  the  Territories,  the  laws 
of  any  State,  or  the  laws  of  any  foreign  country. 

Approved  July  2,  1890. 


SECTIONS  OF  THE  CLAYTON  ACT  ADMINISTERED  BY  THE 
FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION 

(U.  S.  C,  Title  15,  Sec.  12) 
A.N  ACT  To  supplement  existing  laws  against  unlawful  restraints  and  monopolies,  and  for  other  purposes 

Be  it  enacted  by  the  Senate  and  House  of  Representatives  of  the  United  States 
jf  America  in  Congress  assembled,  That  "antitrust  laws,"  as  used  herein,  in- 
cludes the  act  entitled  "An  act  to  protect  trade  and  commerce  against  unlawful 
restraints  and  monopolies,"  approved  July  second,  eighteen  hundred  and  ninety; 
sections  seventy-three  to  seventy-seven,  inclusive,  of  an  act  entitled  "An  act  to 
reduce  taxation,  to  provide  revenue  for  the  Government,  and  for  other  pur- 
poses," of  August  twenty-seventh,  eighteen  hundred  and  ninety-four;  an  act 
entitled  "An  act  to  amend  sections  seventy-three  and  seventy-six  of  the  act  of 
August  twenty-seventh,  eighteen  hundred  and  ninety-four,  entitled  'An  act  to 
reduce  taxation,  to  provide  revenue  for  the  Government,  and  for  other  pur- 
poses,' "  approved  February  twelfth,  nineteen  hundred  and  thirteen;  and  also 
this  act. 

"Commerce,"  as  used  herein,  means  trade  or  commerce  among  the  several 
States  and  with  foreign  nations,  or  between  the  District  of  Columbia  or  any 
Perritory  of  the  United  States  and  any  State,  Territory,  or  foreign  nation,  or 
oetween  any  insular  possessions  or  other  places  under  the  jurisdiction  of  the 
United  States,  or  between  any  such  possession  or  i^lace  and  any  State  or  Terri- 
tory of  the  United  States  or  the  District  of  Columbia  or  any  foreign  nation,  or 
kvithin  tlio  District  of  Columbia  or  any  Territory  or  any  insular  possession  or 
)thor  place  under  the  jurisdiction  of  the  United  States:  Provided,  That  nothing 
n  this  act  contained  shall  apply  to  the  Plulii)i)ine  Islands. 

The  word  "person"  or  "i)ersons"  wherever  used  in  this  act  shall  be  deemed 
jO  include  corporations  and  associations  existing  under  or  authorized  by  the 
aws  of  either  the  Ignited  States,  the  laws  of  any  of  the  Territories,  the  laws 
)f  any  State,  or  the  laws  of  any  foreign  country. 

Sec.  2.1  (a)  That  it  shall  be  unlawful  for  any  person  engaged  in  commerce, 

'  This  section  of  the  Chyton  .\pt  contains  the  provisions  of  the  Robinson-Patman  Anti-Discrimination 
\.et,  approved  June  19,  19:ifi,  uineiuiing  section  2  of  the  original  Clayton  Act,  approved  October  15,  1914. 
For  certain  exemptions  from  llu-  provisions  of  the  later  act  concerning  cooperatives  and  purchases  for  their 
)wn  use  by  schools,  colleges,  universities,  public  libraries,  churches,  hospitals,  and  charitable  institutions 
lot  operated  for  profit,  see  the  later  act  as  published  at  p.  108. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  103 

in  the  course  of  such  commerce,  either  directly  or  indirectly,  to  discriminate  in 
price  between  different  purchasers  of  commodities  of  like  grade  and  quality, 
where  either  or  any  of  the  purchases  involved  in  such  discrimination  are  in 
commerce,  where  such  commodities  are  sold  for  use,  consumption,  or  resale 
within  the  United  States  or  any  Territory  thereof  or  the  District  of  Columbia  or 
any  insular  possession  or  other  place  under  the  jurisdiction  of  the  United  States, 
and  where  the  effect  of  such  discrimination  may  be  substantially  to  lessen  com- 
petition or  tend  to  create  a  monopoly  in  any  line  of  commerce,  or  to  injure,  destroy 
or  prevent  competition  with  any  person  who  either  grants  or  knowingly  receives 
the  benefit  of  such  discrimination,  or  with  customers  of  either  of  them:  Provided, 
That  nothing  herein  contained  shall  prevent  differentials  which  make  only  due 
allowance  for  differences  in  the  cost  of  manufacture,  sale,  or  delivery  resulting 
from  the  differing  methods  or  quantities  in  which  such  commodities  are  to  such 
purchasers  sold  or  delivered:  Provided,  however.  That  the  Federal  'J'rade  Commis- 
sion may,  after  due  investigation  and  hearing  to  all  interested  parties,  fix  and 
establish  quantity  limits,  and  revise  the  same  as  it  finds  necessary,  as  to  particular 
commodities  or  classes  of  commodities,  where  it  finds  that  available  purchasers 
in  greater  quantities  are  so  few  as  to  render  differentials  on  account  thereof  un- 
justly discriminatory  or  promotive  of  monopoly  in  any  line  of  commerce;  and  the 
foregoing  shall  then  not  be  construed  to  permit  differentials  based  on  differences 
in  quantities  greater  than  those  so  fixed  and  established:  And  provided  further,  That 
nothing  herein  contained  shall  prevent  persons  engaged  in  selling  goods,  wares,  or 
merchandise  in  commerce  from  selecting  their  own  customers  in  bona  fide  transac- 
tions and  not  in  restraint  of  trade:  And  -provided  further,  That  nothing  herein 
contained  shall  prevent  price  changes  from  time  to  time  where  in  response  to 
changing  conditions *affecting  the  market  for  or  the  marketability  of  the  goods 
concerned,  such  as  but  not  limited  to  actual  or  imminent  deterioration  of  perishable 
goods,  obsolescense  of  seasonal  goods,  distress  sales  under  court  process,  or  sales 
in  good  faith  in  discontinuance  of  business  in  the  goods  concerned. 

(b)  Upon  proof  being  made,  at  any  hearing  on  a  complaint  under  this  section, 
that  there  has  been  discrimination  in  price  or  services  or  facilities  furnished, 
the  burden  of  rebutting  the  prima  facie  case  thus  made  by  showing  justification 
shall  be  upon  the  person  charged  with  a  violation  of  this  section,  and  unless 
justification  shall  be  affirmatively  shown,  the  Commission  is  authorized  to  issue 
an  order  terminating  the  discrimination:  Provided,  however.  That  nothing 
herein  contained  shall  prevent  a  seller  rebutting  the  prima  facie  case  thus  made  by 
showing  that  his  lower  price  or  the  furnishing  of  services  or  facilities 
to  any  purchaser  or  purchasers  was  made  in  good  faith  to  meet  an  equally 
low  price  of  a  competitor,  or  the  services  or  facilities  furnished  by  a  competitor. 

(c)  That  it  shall  be  unlawful  for  any  person  engaged  in  commerce,  in  the 
course  of  such  commerce,  to  pay  or  grant,  or  to  receive  or  accept,  anything 
of  value  as  a  commission,  brokerage,  or  other  compensation,  or  any  allowance 
or  discount  in  lieu  thereof,  except  for  services  rendered  in  connection  with 
the  sale  or  purchase  of  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise,  either  to  the  other  party 
to  such  transaction  or  to  an  agent,  representative,  or  other  intermediary  therein 
where  such  internaediary  is  acting  in  fact  for  or  in  behalf,  or  is  subject  to  the 
direct  or  indirect  control,  of  any  party  to  such  transaction  other  than  the  person 
by  whom  such  compensation  is  so  granted  or  paid. 

•(d)  That  it  shall  be  unlawful  for  any  person  engaged  in  commerce  to  pay 
or  contract  for  the  payment  of  anything  of  value  to  or  for  the  benefit  of  a 
customer  of  such  person  in  the  course  of  such  commerce  as  compensation  or 
in  consideration  for  any  services  or  facilities  furnished  by  or  through  such 
customer  in  connection  with  the  processing,  handling,  sale,  or  offering  for  sale 
to  any  products  or  commodities  manufactured,  sold,  or  offered  for  sale  by  such 
person,  unless  such  payment  or  consideration  is  available  on  proportionally 
equal  terms  to  all  other  customers  competing  in  the  distribution  of  such  prod- 
ucts or  commodities. 

(e)  That  it  shall  be  unlawful  for  any  person  to  discriminate  in  favor  of  one 
purchaser  against  another  purchaser  or  purchasers  of  a  commodity  bought  for 
resale,  with  or  without  processing,  by  contracting  to  furnish  or  furnishing,  or 
by  contributing  to  the  furnishing  of,  any  services  or  facilities  connected  with 
the  processing,  handling,  sale,  or  offering  for  sale  of  such  commodity  so  pur- 
chased upon  terms  not  accorded  to  all  purchasers  on  proportionally  ccjual  terms. 

(f)  That  it  shall  be  unlawful  for  any  person  engaged  in  commerce,  in  the 
course  of  such  commerce,  knowingly  to  induce  or  receive  a  discrimination  in 
price  which  is  prohibited  by  this  section. 

i^  ^  *  *  *  *  * 


J[Q4  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Sec.  3.  That  it  shall  be  unlawful  for  any  person  engaged  in  commerce,  in  the 
course  ol  such  commerce,  to  lease  or  make  a  sale  or  contract  for  sale  of  goods, 
wares,  merchandise,  machinery,  supplies,  or  other  commodities,  whether  pat- 
ented or  unpatented,  for  use,  consumption,  or  resale  within  the  United  States 
or  any  Territory  thereof,  or  the  District  of  Columbia,  or  any  irfsular  possession 
or  other  place  under  the  jurisdiction  of  the  United  States,  or  fix  a  price  charged 
therefor,  or  discount  from,  or  rebate  upon,  such  price,  on  the  condition,  agree- 
ment, or  understanding  that  the  lessee  or  purchaser  thereof  shall  not  use  or 
deal  in  the  goods,  wares,  merchandise,  machinery,  supplies,  or  other  com- 
modities of  a  competitor  or  competitors  of  the  lessor  or  seller,  where  the  effect 
of  such  lease,  sale,  or  contract  tor  sale  or  such  condition,  agreement,  or  under- 
standing may  be  to  substantially  lessen  competition  or  tend  to  create  a  monopoly 
in  any  line  of  commerce. 

Sec.  7.  That  no  corporation  engaged  in  commerce  shall  acquire,  directly  or 
indirectly,  the  whole  or  any  part  of  the  stock  or  other  share  capital  of  another 
corporation  engaged  also  in  commerce,  where  the  effect  of  such  acquisition  may 
be  to  substantially  lessen  competition  between  the  corporation  whose  stock  is 
so  acquired  and  the  corporation  making  the  acquisition,  or  to  restrain  such 
commerce  in  any  section  or  coinmunity,  or  tend  to  create  a  monopoly  of  any 
line  of  commerce. 

No  corporation  shall  acquire,  directly  or  indirectly,  the  w^hole  or  any  part 
of  the  stock  or  other  share  capital  of  two  or  more  corporations  engaged  in 
commerce  where  the  effect  of  such  acquisition,  or  the  use  of  such  stock  by  the 
voting  or  granting  of  proxies  or  otherw^ise,  may  be  to  substaritially  lessen  compe- 
tition between  such  corporations,  or  any  of  theiB,  whose  stock  or  other  share 
capital  is  so  acquired,  or  restrain  such  commerce  in  any  section  or  community, 
or  tend  to  create  a  monopoly  of  any  line  of  commerce. 

This  section  shall  not  apply  to  corporations  purchasing  such  stock  solely  for 
investment  and  not  using  the  same  by  voting  or  otherwise  to  bring  about,  or 
in  attempting  to  bring  about,  the  substantial  lessening  of  competition.  Nor 
shall  anything  contained  in  this  section  prevent  a  corporation  engaged  in  com- 
merce from  causing  the  formation  of  subsidiary  corporations  for  the  actual 
carrying  on  of  their  immediate  lawful  business,  or  the  natural  and  legitimate 
branches  or  extensions  thereof,  or  from  owning  and  holding  all  or  a  part  of  the 
stock  of  such  subsidiary  corporations,  when  the  effect  of  such  formation  is  not 
to  substantially  lessen  competition. 

Nor  shall  anything  herein  contained  be  construed  to  prohibit  any  common 
carrier  subject  to  the  laws  to  regulate  commerce  from  aiding  in  the  construction 
of  branches  or  short  lines  so  located  as  to  become  feeders  to  the  main  line  of  the 
company  so  aiding  in  such  construction  or  from  acquiring  or  owning  all  or  any 
part  of  the  stock  of  such  branch  lines,  nor  to  prevent  any  such  common  carrier 
from  acquiring  and  owning  all  or  any  part  of  the  stock  of  a  branch  or  short  line 
constructed  by  an  independent  company  where  there  is  no  substantial  competi- 
tion between  the  company  owning  the  branch  line  so  constructed  and  the  com- 
pany owning  the  main  line  acquiring  the  property  or  an  interest  therein,  nor  to 
prevent  such  common  carrier  from  extending  any  of  its  lines  through  the  medium 
of  the  acquisition  of  stock  or  otherwise  of  any  other  such  common  carrier  where 
there  is  no  substantial  competition  between  the  company  extending  its  lines  and 
the  company  whose  stock,  property,  or  an  interest  therein  is  so  acquired. 

Nothing  contained  in  this  section  shall  be  held  to  affect  or  impair  any  right 
heretofore  legally  acquired:  Provided,  That  nothing  in  this  section  shall  be  held 
or  construed  to  authorize  or  make  lawful  anything  lieretofore  prohibited  or  made 
illegal  by  the  antitrust  laws,  nor  to  exempt  any  person  from  the  penal  provisions 
thereof  or  the  civil  remedies  therein  provided. 

Sec.  8.  *  *  *  That  from  and  after  two  years  from  the  date  of  the  ap- 
proval of  this  act  no  person  at  the  same  time  shall  be  a  director  in  any  two  or 
more  corporations,  any  one  of  which  has  capital,  surplus,  and  undivided  profits 
aggregating  more  than  $1,000,000,  engaged  in  whole  or  in  part  in  commerce, 
other  than  l)anks,  banking  associations,  trust  companies,  and  common  carriers 
sut)ject  to  the  act  to  regulate  commerce,  approved  February  fourth,  eighteen 
Iiundred  and  eighty-seven,  if  such  corporations  are  or  shall  have  been  thereto- 
fore, by  virtue  of  their  business  and  location  of  operation,  competitors,  so  that 
the  elimination  of  competition  by  agreement  between  them  would  constitute  a 
violation  of  any  of  the  provisions  of  any  of  the  antitrust  laws.  The  eligibility 
of  a  director  under  the  foregoing  provision  shall  be  determined  by  the  agree- 
gate  amount  of  the  capital,  surplus,  and  undivided  profits,  exclusive  of  dividends 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


105 


declared  but  not  paid  to  stockholders,  at  the  end  of  the  fiscal  year  of  said  corpo- 
ration next  preceding  the  election  of  directors,  and  when  a  director  has  been 
elected  in  accordance  with  the  i:)rovisions  of  this  act  it  shall  Ije  lawful  for  him  to 
continue  as  such  for  one  year  thereafter. 

When  any  person  elected  or  chosen  as  a  director  or  officer  or  selected  as  an 
employee  of  any  bank  or  other  corporation  subject  to  the  provisions  of  this 
act  is  eligible  at  the  time  of  his  election  or  selection  to  act  for  such  bank  or 
other  corporation  in  such  capacity  his  eligibility  to  act  in  such  capacity  shall 
not  be  affected  and  he  shall  not  become  or  be  deemed  amenable  to  any  of  the 
provisions  hereof  by  reason  of  any  change  in  the  affairs  of  such  bank  or  other 
corporation  from  whatsoever  cause,  whether  specifically  excepted  by  any  of  the 
provisions  hereof  or  not,  until  the  expiration  of  one  year  from  the  date  of  his 
election  or  employment. 

******* 
Sec.  11.  That  authority  to  enforce  compliance  with  sections  two,  three,  seven, 
and  eight  of  this  Act  by  the  persons  respectively  subject  thereto  is  hereby  vested; 
in  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  where  applicable  to  common  carriers 
subject  to  the  Interstate  Commerce  Act,  as  amended;  in  the  Federal  Communica- 
tions Commission  where  applicable  to  common  carriers  engaged  in  wire  or  radio 
communication  or  radio  transmission  of  energy;  in  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Au- 
thority where  applicable  to  air  carriers  and  foreign  air  carriers  subject  to  the 
Civil  Aeronautics  Act  of  1938;  ^  in  the  Federal  Reserve  Board  where  applicable  to 
banks,  banking  associations,  and  trust  companies;  and  in  the  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission where  applicable  to  all  other  character  of  commerce,  to  be  exercised  as 
follows : 

Whenever  the  commission,  authorit}',  or  board  vested  with  jurisdiction  thereof 
shall  have  reason  to  believe  that  any  person  is  violating  or  has  violated  any 
of  the  provisions  of  sections  two,  three,  seven,  and  eight  of  this  Act,  it  shall 
issue  and  serve  upon  such  person  a  complaint  stating  its  charges  in  that  respect, 
and  containing  a  notice  of  a  hearing  upon  a  day  and  at  a  place  therein  fixed  at 
least  thirty  days  after  the  service  of  said  complaint.  The  person  so  complained 
of  shall  have  the  right  to  appear  at  the  place  and  time  so  fixed  and  show  cause 
why  an  order  should  not  be  entered  by  the  commission,  authority,  or  board 
requiring  such  person  to  cease  and  desist  from  the  violation  of  the  law  so  charged 
in  said  complaint.  Any  person  may  make  application,  and  upon  good  cause 
shown  may  be  allowed  by  the  commission,  authority,  or  board,  to  intervene 
and  appear  in  said  proceeding  by  counsel  or  in  person.  The  testimony  in  any 
such  proceeding  shall  be  reduced  to  writing  and  filed  in  the  office  of  the  commis- 
sion, authority,  or  board.  If  upon  such  hearing  the  commission,  authority,  or 
board,  as  the  case  may  be,  shall  be  of  the  opinion  that  any  of  the  provisions  of 
said  sections  have  been  or  are  being  violated,  it  shall  make  a  report  in  writing  in 
which  it  shall  state  its  findings  as  to  the  facts,  and  shall  issue  and  cause  to  be 
served  on  such  persons  an  order  requiring  such  person  to  cease  and  desist  from 
such  violations,  and  divest  itself  of  the  stock  held  or  rid  itself  of  the  directors 
chosen  contrary  to  the  provisions  of  sections  seven  and  eight  of  this  Act,  if  any 
there  be,  in  the  manner  and  within  the  time  fixed  by  said  order.  Until  a  trans- 
cript of  the  record  in  such  hearing  shall  have  been  filed  in  a  circuit  court  of  appeals 
of  the  United  States,  as  hereinafter  provided,  the  commission,  authority,  or  board 
may  at  any  time,  upon  such  notice  and  in  such  manner  as  it  shall  deem  proper, 
modify  or  set  aside,  in  whole  or  in  part,  any  report  of  any  order  made  or  issued 
by  it  under  this  section. 

If  such  person  fails  or  neglects  to  obey  such  order  of  the  commission,  author- 
ity, or  board  while  the  same  is  in  effect,  the  commission,  authority,  or  board 
may  apply  to  the  circuit  court  of  appeals  of  the  United  States,  within  any  circuit 
where  the  violation  complained  of  was  or  is  being  committed  or  where  such 
person  resides  or  carries  on  business,  for  the  enforcement  of  its  order,  and  shall 
certify  and  file  with  its  application  a  transcript  of  the  entire  record  in  the  pro- 
ceeding, including  all  the  testimony  taken  and  the  report  and  order  of  the  com- 
mission, authority  or  board.     Upon  such  filing  of  the  application  and  transcript 

2  By  subsection  (g)  of  section  1107  of  the  "Civil  Aeronautics  Act  of  1938,"  approved  Tune  23,  1938,  Public, 
No.  706,  75th  Cong.,  Ch.  601,3d  sess.,  S.  3845, 52  Stat.  1028,  section  11  of  the  Act  of  October  15,  1914,  the  Clay- 
ton Act,  was  amended  by  inserting  after  the  word  "energy"  (in  the  sixth  line  from  the  beginning  of  the 
paragraph,  reading  "wire  or  radio  communication  or  radio  transmission  of  energy:"),  the  following:  "in 
the  Civil  Aeronautics  Authority  where  applicable  to  air  carriers  and  foreign  air  carriers  subject  to  the  Civil 
Aeronautics  Act  of  1938;"  and  by  inserting  after  the  word  "commission"  wherever  it  appears  in  that  section 
a  comma  and  the  word  "authority." 

291144 — 41 — No.  38 8 


IQQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

the  court  shall  cause  notice  thereof  to  be  served  upon  such  person  and  thereupon 
shall  have  jurisdiction  of  the  proceeding  and  of  the  question  determined  therein, 
and  shall  have  power  to  make  and  enter  upon  the  pleadings,  testimony,  and 
proceedings  set  forth  in  such  transcript  a  decree  affirming,  modifying,  or  setting 
aside  the  order  of  the  commission,  authority,  or  board.  The  findings  of  the 
commission,  authority,  or  board  as  to  the  facts,  if  supported  by  testimony,  shall 
be  conclusive.  If  either  party  shall  apply  to  the  court  for  leave  to  adduce  addi- 
tional evidence,  and  shall  show  to  the  satisfaction  of  the  court  that  such  additional 
evidence  is  material  and  that  there  were  reasonable  grounds  for  the  failure  to 
adduce  such  evidence  in  the  proceeding  before  the  commission,  authority,  or 
board,  the  court  may  order  such  additional  evidence  to  be  taken  before  the 
commission,  authority,  or  board  and  to  be  adduced  upon  the  hearing  in  such 
manner  and  upon  such  terms  and  conditions  as  to  the  court  may  seem  proper. 
The  commission,  authority,  or  board  may  modify  its  findings  as  to  the  facts,  or 
make  new  findings,  by  reason  of  the  additional  evidence  so  taken,  and  it  shall 
file  such  modified  or  new  findings,  which,  if  supported  by  testimony,  shall  be 
conclusive,  and  its  recommendations,  if  any,  for  the  modification  or  setting  aside 
of  its  original  order,  with  the  return  of  such  additional  evidence.  The  judgment 
and  decree  of  the  court  shall  be  final,  except  that  the  same  shall  be  subject  to 
review  by  the  Supreme  Court  upon  certiorari  as  provided  in  section  240  of  the 
Judicial  Code. 

Any  party  required  b}^  such  order  of  the  commission,  authority,  or  board  to 
cease  and  desist  from  a  violation  charged  may  obtain  a  review  of  such  order 
in  said  circuit  court  of  appeals  by  filing  in  the  court  a  written  petition  praying 
that  the  order  of  the  commission,  authority,  or  board  be  set  aside.  A  copy  of 
such  petition  shall  be  forthwith  served  upon  the  commission,  authority,  or  board, 
and  thereupon  the  commission,  authority,  or  board  forthwith  shall  certify  and 
file  in  the  court  a  transcript  of  the  record  as  hereinbefore  provided.  Upon  the 
filing  of  the  transcript  the  court  shall  have  the  same  jurisdiction  to  affirm, 
set  aside,  or  modify  the  order  of  the  commission,  authority,  or  board  as  in  the 
case  of  an  application  by  the  commission,  authority,  or  board  for  the  enforce- 
ment of  its  order,  and  the  findings  of  the  commission,  authority,  or  board  as 
to  the  facts,  if  supported  by  testimony,  shall  in  like  manner  be  conclusive. 

The  jurisdiction  of  the  circuit  court  of  appeals  of  the  United  States  to  enforce, 
set  aside,  or  modify  orders  of  the  commission,  authority,  or  board  shall  be  exclusive. 

Such  proceedings  in  the  circuit  court  of  appeals  shall  be  given  precedence  over 
other  cases  pending  therein,  and  shall  be  in  every  way  expedited.  No  order  of 
the  commission,  authority,  or  board,  or  the  judgment  of  the  court  to  enforce 
the  same  shall  in  any  wise  relieve  or  absolve  any  person  from  any  liability  under 
the  antitrust  Acts. 

Complaints,  orders,  and  other  processes  of  the  commission,  authority,  or  board 
under  this  section  may  be  served  by  anyone  duly  authorized  by  the  commission, 
authority,  or  board,  either  (a)  by  delivering  a  copy  thereof  to  the  person  to  be 
served,  or  to  a  member  of  the  partnership  to  be  served,  or  to  the  president, 
secretary,  or  other  executive  officer  or  a  director  of  the  corporation  to  be  served; 
or  (b)  by  leaving  a  copy  thereof  at  the  principal  office  or  place  of  business  of 
such  person;  or  (c)  by  registering  and  mailing  a  copy  thereof  addressed  to  such 
person  at  his  principal  office  or  place  of  business.  The  verified  return  by  the 
person  so  serving  said  complaint,  order,  or  other  process  setting  forth  the  man- 
ner of  said  service  shall  be  proof  of  the  same,  and  the  return  post-office  receipt 
for  said  complaint,  order,  or  other  process  registered  and  mailed  as  aforesaid 
shall  be  proof  of  the  service  of  the  same. 

******* 

Approved  October  15,  1914. 


GENERAL    BOOKBINDfNG    CO.