Skip to main content

Full text of "Investigation of concentration of economic power; monograph no. 1[-43]"

See other formats


"^3d  Sessfon^^l        SENATE  COMMITTEE  PRINT 


INVESTIGATION  OF  CONCENTRATION 
OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


TEMPORARY  NATIONAL  ECONOMIC 
COMMITTEE 


A  STUDY  MADE  UNDER  THE  AUSPICES  OF  THE  BUREAU 
OF  LABOR  STATISTICS  FOR  THE  TEMPORARY  NATIONAL 
ECONOMIC  COMMITTEE,  SEVENTY-SIXTH  CONGRESS, 
THIRD  SESSION,  PURSUANT  TO  PUBLIC  RESOLUTION  NO. 
113  (SEVENTY-FIFTH  CONGRESS),  AUTHORIZING  AND 
DIRECTING  A  SELECT  COMMITTEE  TO  MAKE  A  FULL  AND 
COMPLETE  STUDY  AND  INVESTIGATION  WITH  RESPECT 
TO  THE  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  IN,  AND 
FINANCIAL  CONTROL  OVER,  PRODUCTION  AND 
DISTRIBUTION  OF  GOODS  AND  SERVICES 


MONOGRAPH  No.  1-3 
PRICE  BEHAVIOR  AND  BUSINESS  POLICY 


Printed  for  the  use  of  the 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee 


U 


UNITED  STATES  CA, 

GOVERNMENT  PRINTING  OFFICE 
WASHINGTON  :   1941 


northeaster;^  UNiVEKoiTV  SCHOOL  of  LAW  OBi??^ 


TEMPORARY  NATIONAL  ECONOMIC  COMMITTEE 

(Created  pursuant  to  Public  Res.  113,  75th  Cong.) 

JOSEPH  C.  O'MAIIONEY,  Senator  from  Wyoming,  Chairman 

HATTON  W.  SUMNERS,  Representative  from  Texas,  Vice  Chairman 

WILLIAM  H.  KINO,  Senator  from  Utah 

WALLACE  H.  WHITE,  Jr.,  Senator  from  Maine 

CLYDE  WILLIAMS,  Representative  from  Missouri 

B.  CARROLL  REECE,  Representative  from  Tennessee 

THURMAN  W.  ARNOLD,  Assistant  Attorney  General 

♦WENDELL  BERQE,  Special  Assistant  to  the  Attorney  General 

Representing  the  Department  of  Justice 

JEROME  N.  FRANK,  Chairman 

•SUMNER  T.  PIKE,  Commissioner 

Representing  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission 

GARLAND  S.  FERGUSON,  Commissioner 

•EWIN  L.  DAVIS,  Chairman  O^^    \. 

Representing  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  f  f^\ 

ISADOR  LUBIN,  Commissioner  of  Labor  Statistics  CT>' 

•A.  FORD  HINRICHS,  Chief  EconomLst,  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  '' 

Representing  the  Department  of  Labor 
JOSEPH  J.  O'CONNELL,  Jr.,  Special  Assistant  to  the  General  Counsel  ~^ 

•CHARLES  L.  KADES,  Special  Assistant  to  the  General  Counsel 

Representing  the  Department  of  the  Treasury  f  "t 

ijj 

Representing  the  Department  of  Commerce  f—^ 

LEON  HENDERSON,  Economic  Coordinator 
DEWEY  ANDERSON,  Executive  Secretary 
THEODORE  J.  KREPS,  Economic  Adviser 
♦Alternates. 


Monograph  No.  1 
PRICE  BEHAVIOR  AND  BUSINESS  POLICY 

BY 

SAUL  NELSON  AND  WALTER  Q.  KEIM 

ASSISTED  BY 

LAURA  MAE  BROWN,  JOHN  M.  BLAIR,  AND  WILLIAM  C.  FRENCH,  JR.,  UNDER  THE 
GENERAL  SUPERVISION  OF  ARYNESS  JOY  AND  EDWARD  S.  MASON 


REPRINTED 

BY 

WILLIAM    S    HEIN    &  CO  ,  INC 

BUFFALO.  N.  Y. 
1968 


ACKNOWLEDGMENT 

This  monograph  was  written  by 

SAtJL  NELSON 
Senior  Industrial  Economist, 
Bureau    of    Labor    Statistics 

AND 

WALTER  G.  KEIM 

Statistician, 
Bureau    of    Labor    Statistics 

under  the  supervision  of 

EDWARD    S.  MASON 

Professor  oj  Economics, 
Harvard  University 

The  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  is  greatly  indebted 
to  these  authors  for  this  contribution  to  the  literature  of  the  subject 
under  review. 

The  status  of  the  materials  in  this  volume  is  precisely  the  same  as  that 
of  other  carefully  prepared  testimony  when  given  by  individual  witnesses; 
it  is  information  submitted  for  Committee  deliberation.  No  matter  what 
the  official  capacity  of  the  witness  or  author  may  be,  the  publication  of 
his  testimony,  report,  or  monograph  by  the  Committee  in  no  way  signifies 
nor  implies  assent  to,  or  approval  of,  any  of  the  facts,  opinions  or  recom- 
mendations, nor  acceptance  thereof  in  whole  or  in  part  by  the  members 
of  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  individually  or 
collectively.  Sole  and  undivided  responsibility  for  every  statement  in 
such  testimony,  reports,  or  monographs  rests  entirely  upon  the  respective 
authors. 

(Signed)     Joseph  C.  O'Mahoney, 
Chairman,  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee. 

m 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


Pas* 

Letter  of  transmittal _ xv 

Summary . xix 

PART  I 

Preface 3 

CHAPTER   1 

Price  Behavior  and  Business  Policy __ 4 

CHAPTER    II 

Price  Flexibil ity 11 

Summary . 11 

The  nature  of  the  problem 14 

The  meaning  of  flexibility 20 

The  measurement  of  price  flexijjility 27 

The  distinction  between  measures  of  behavior  and  of  responsive- 
ness  - 27 

The  specific  measures  utilized 29 

Measures  of  flexibility  compared 31 

Factors  affecting  price  behavior 32 

Prices  and  production.. ^ 37 

Price  relationships 43 

Cost-price  relationships 60 

Conclusions 51 

CHAPTER    III 

Nonprice  Competition . _  64 

Summary 64 

Price  versus  nonprice  competition — the  setting  of  the  problem 68 

The  changing  focus  of  competition 68 

Prices  related  to  nonprice  elements  of  the  transaction 63 

Aspects  of  nonprice  competition 63 

Quality  and  performance 63 

Guarantees -  69 

Price  lines 70 

Advertising,  brands,  and  trade-marks 76 

Other  forms  of  nonprice  competition — escape  devices 90 

Conclusions 101 

CHAPTER    IV 

The  Electrical  Equipment  Industries — An  Illustrative  Case 109 

Summary . 109 

Price  and  production  trends 111 

Market  saturation 117 

Saturation  by  income  groups.. 120 

Expenditures  by  families 130 

Income  residuals 130 

Competition  and  sales  strategy 131 

Price  uniformity 131 

Concentrat  ion 134 

Emphasis  upon  quality .--»-.  135 

The  turning  point — the  1937-38  recession 137 

Problems  of  sales  policy  determination 138 


VI  TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 

Page 
The  Electrical  Equipment  Industries — An  Illustrative  Case — Continued. 

Expanding  the  original  sales  market -- 138 

Quality  emphasis  and  advertising 138 

Credit  terms ---  141 

Price  reductions 141 

Reductions  in  the  cost  of  manufacturing. — 143 

Distribution  costs 143 

The  replacement  market 148 

Need  for  considering  the  replacement  market •- 148 

Extent  of  replacement  sales 148 

Factors  influencing  replacement  sales 149 

Durability 149 

Obsolescence 149 

Cost  of  replacement — the  trade-in  allowance 150 

Facilities  for  reconditioning  equipilnent — -the  Crosley  plan 152 

The  Philadelphia  plan 153 

Reconditioning  exchange  system  in  vacuum  cleaners 153 

Summary 153 

Current  trends  in  the  electrical  refrigerator  industry _  154 

The  role  of  Government- 158 

Conclusions 161 

APPENDIX  I 

Measures  of  Price  Flexibility 165 

Purpose 165 

The  criteria  utilized 166 

Presentation  of  the  data 168 

Relationships  between  the  measures  presented 169 

Depression  decline  compared  with  extent  of  recovery 170 

Relationships  between  various  aspects  of  timing 170 

Frequency  of  change  and  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement 170 

Frequency  and  timing.. 171 

Amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  and  timing  of  change 171 

Change  per  change  compared  with  frequency,  cyclical  flexibility, 

and  timing 171 

Aggregate  change  less  net  change 171 

APPENDIX   n 

Conventional  Price  Lines 242 

Introduction  -.1 : 242 

Wearing  apparel 242 

Corsets  and  bratsieres 242 

Dresses 244 

Girls'  cotton  dresses 246 

Coats _• 247 

Women's  hose 247 

Girls'  anklets , ,. 247 

Men's  work  shirts -_«_. 248 

Yard  goods 248 

Consumers'  durable  goods 249 

Washing  machines  and  vacuum  cleaners 249 

Radios 249 

Refrigerators 249 

The  cash  di^ount  in  the  apparel  market : 250 

APPENDIX   III 

Statistical  Data  Supporting  Charts ._  252-265 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS  VII 

PART  II  Page 

Preface 269 

CHAPTER    I 

Types  of  Geographic  Price  Structure 271 

Introduction 271 

The  importance  of  transportation  costs. 271 

Factors  affecting  freight  costs 272 

Economic  significance 272 

Types  of  structure  summarized 273 

Common  forms  of  structure — development  and  characteristics 275 

.    F.  0.  b.  plant  prices 275 

Freight  equalization 276 

Basing  point  systems 279 

Postage  stamp  and  zone  systems .--.""  ^^^ 

Buyer-dominated  structures — equalization  at  the  point  of  origin.  284 

Unsystematic  price  variation 285 

CHAPTER    II 

Geographic  Practices  in  American  Markets 286 

Methods  of  analysis - 286 

Agricultural  commodities '.-  287 

Wheat - 289 

Milk 290 

Cattle : 290 

Potatoes 290 

Fresh  fruits  and  vegetables 292 

Cottonseed 292 

Food  and  kindred  products 293 

Meats 294 

Vegetable  oils 294 

Vegetable  shortening 295 

Bread 295 

Sugar ..... 295 

Salt 296 

Coffee 298 

Rice 298 

Other  food  products 299 

Textiles  and  textile  products 300 

Yarns-.-. . 300 

Gray  goods - 301 

Finished  cloth 301 

Finished  apparel -  301 

Binder  twine 302 

Manila  rope 303 

Leather  and  its  major  products 303 

leather 303 

Leather  boots  and  shoes 303 

Leather  transmission  belting 304 

Tobacco  products 304 

Cigarettes  and  tobacco 304 

Cigars 305 

Snuff 305 

Steel-  and  steel  products 305 

Other  iron  and  steel  products 308 

Ferro-alloys 308 

Hardware,  tools  and  other  light  fabricated  steel 308 

Lumber  and  its  products 308 

Lumber: 

Douglas  fir 308 

Ponderosa  pine 308 

Southern  pine 309 

Maple  flooring. 309 

Oak  flooring 309 


VIII  TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 

Geographic  Practices  in  American  Markets — Continued, 

Lumber  and  its  products — Continued.  Pago 

Philippine  mahogany 30& 

Mahogany — Honduran,  African,  and  Cuban 309* 

Doors — Douglas  fir  and  Ponderosa  pine 309 

Windows  and  window  frames 309 

Wooden  boxes --^ 309 

Wooden  caskets  and  coffins 309 

Axe  handles 309 

Ladders 309 

Plywood 310 

Summary 310 

Turpentine 310 

Building  materials  other  than  steel  and  lumber 310 

Lime 311 

Cement 311 

Brick 312 

Sand  and  gravel 312 

Building  tile 312 

Floor  tile 312 

Sewer  pipe 312 

Gypsum  plaster 312 

Insulation  board 313 

Prepared  roofing 313 

Heating  boilers  and  radiation 313 

Plumbing  fixtures,  closets,  lavatories,  sinks,  and  bathtubs 314 

Paint  materials: 

Linseed  oil 314 

White  lead 314 

Prepared  paints 314 

Window  glass 315 

Summary 315 

Furn i  tu re  industry 315 

Household  furniture _. 3 15 

Busi  ness  furniture 316 

Chemicals 316 

Simple  f.  o.  b.  plant  systems 318 

Freight  equalization  systems , 318 

Postage  stamp  and  zone  pricing 319 

Zone  differentials  and  changes  in  zone  systems _-  320 

Basing-point  systems 320 

Summar}' 321 

Drugs,  cosmetics  and  toiletries 323 

Fertilizer  and  fertilizer  materials 324 

Fert ilizer  materials 324 

Mixed  fertilizer 326 

Paper  and  pulp  industries 328 

Pulp 328 

Paper 328 

Newsprint 328 

Wrapping  paper,  tissue  paper,  and  paper  towels 329 

Paper  board 329 

Fine  paper 329 

Paper  products 330 

Passenger  automobiles 330 

Agricultural  implements  and  machinery 331 

Machinery  and  related  products 331 

Electrical  machinery  and  apparatus 332 

Milling  machines,  grinding  machines,  screw  machines,  etc 335 

Engines,  turbines,  water  wheels,  and  windmills 335 

Pumps . 335 

Excavating  and  road  machinery 336 

Business  and  trade  equipment 336 

Electrical  household  equipment 336 

Electric  refrigerators .• . 336 

Electric  washing  machines  and  ranges 337 

Vacuum  cleaners  and  fans 338 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS  IK 

Geographic  Practices  in  American  Markets — Continued.  Pag« 

Nonf errous  metals 338 

Aluminum 338 

Zinc _-  338 

Lead . 339 

Copper 1 .- - 339 

Lake  copper 340 

Scrap  metal 340 

Petroleum  and  its  products 341 

Crude  oil 341 

Gasoline 341 

Bituminous  coal 342 

Summary — Extent  of  major  types  of  geographic  price  structure 343 

Uniform  f.  o.  b.  plant  pricing 343 

Uniform  delivered  prices _ 343 

Zone  delivered  prices 344 

Freight  equalization 344 

Basing-point  industries 345 

Local  markets 345 

Unsystematic  variation 345 

PART  III 

CHAPTER   I 

Preface - 349 

General  Characteristics  of  the  Market 351 

Resale  price  controls 352 

CHAPTER   11 

Retail  Markets 355 

Retail  price  trends,  1929-39 355 

Analgesic  tablets 356 

A  drug  sundry 357 

A  shaving  article 358 

A  dentifrice _  360 

A  nationally  advertised  liquid  laxative 360 

A  standard,  unbranded,  liquid  laxative 360 

Price  trends — chains  compared  with  independents 361 

Retail  prices  as  reported  by  the  marketing  laws  survey 365 

Advertised  and  substitute  brands 368 

Substitute  brands  and  resale  price  maintenance 379 

Price  lines 382 

CHAPTER   in 

Distributive  Margins 386 

Methods  of  distribution 386 

Wholesale  and  retail  margins 388 

The  range  of  margins 388 

Pharmaceutical: 

"A" 388 

"B"_. , 390 

Drug  sundry ^ , 392 

Toiletries: 

"A" 393 

"B" .- 395 

"C" _ - 396 

Cosmetic: 

"A" 397 

"B" .___ --_  398 

"C" 399 

Summary  for  eight  products 400 

Margins  allowed  by  a  large  drug  manufacturer 402 

Mark-ups  for  cosmetics 403 

Mark-ups  in  California 404 

Summary , 404 


X  TABLE  OF  CX)NTENTS 

SCHEDULE  OF  TABLES  AND  CHARTS 

PART  I 

TABLES 

Page 

1.  Median   change   in   price   and   quantity   available   for   consumption 

1929-32,  for  111  commodities,  classified  according  to  durability 38 

2.  Selected  indexes  of  prices,  wages,  costs  of  distribution,  farm  taxes, 

and  mortgage  interest,  1913-38 49 

3.  Changes  in  size  of  chocolate  bars 73 

4.  Prices  and  quality  grades  for  specified  brands  of  canned  foods 77 

5.  Extent  of  consumer  brand  preference  for  prepared  foods _  79 

6.  Comparison  of  wholesale  prices  of  identical  substances  sold  under 

proprietary  and  nonproprietary  names 81 

7.  Comparison  of  retail  prices  of  drugs,  cosmetics,  and  foods  with  the 

costs  of  their  ingredients 82 

8.  Relation  of  price  flexibility  to  importance  of  brand  preference 86 

9.  Comparison  of  quoted  prices  for  sulphuric  acid  with  prices  actually 

paid  by  a  large  buyer 99 

10.  Average  retail  value  and  sales  of  selected  electrical  appliances 112 

11.  Saturation  of  the  market 118 

12.  Market  saturation  and  sales i 118 

13.  Average   expenditures   by   families  •  of   employed   wage   earners   and 

clerical  workers,  by  economic  level 130 

14.  Distributive  margin  of  electric  refrigerators 144 

15.  Distributive  margin  of  electric  washing  machines •__ __  144 

16.  Distribution  of  sales  and  average  value  of  electric  washing  machines 

by  price  lines — 1938 -.  144 

17.  Distributive  margins 145 

18.  Replacement  sales  as  a  percent  of  total  sales  of  electric  refrigerators.  _  148 

19.  Estimated  durability  of  electric  refrigerators 149 

20.  Retail  published  list  prices  of  electrical  refrigerators — 1939  and  1940.   155-156 

21.  List  prices  of  electric  refrigerators,  1938 — principal  companies 162 

22.  Percent  of  concentration,  1937 163 

23.  Cash  value  on  trade-ins 163 

24.  Average   expenditures   by   families   of   employed   wage   earners   and 

clerical  workers  by  economic  level 164 

25.  Flexibility  of  commodity  prices  measured  by  various  criteria^ 172-189* 

26.  Flexibility  of  commodity  prices  measured  by  various  criteria  ranked  in 

ten  groups  for  each  criterion  in  order  of  increasing  flexibility 190-210 

27-44.  Correlation  tables  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their 

ranks  by  two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 211-228 

27.  Percent  of  decline,  1929  to  1933,  compared  with  percent  of  recovery, 

1933  to  1937 211 

28.  Timing  of  predepression  peak,  1929  to  1931,  compared  with  timing  of 

depression  low,  1932  to  1934 212 

29.  Timing  of  predepression   peak,   1929   to    1931,  compared  with  post- 

depression  peak,  1936  to  1938 213 

30.  Timing  of  depression  low,  1932  to  1934,  compared  with  post  depression 

peak,  1936  to  1938 214 

31-34.  Frequency  of  change  compared  with  amplitude  of  cyclical  move- 
ment   215-218 

35.  Frequency  of  change  compared  with  timing  of  predepression  peak, 

1929to  1931 219 

36.  Frequency  of  change  compared  with  timing  of  depression  low,  1932  to 

1934 220 

37.  Frequencv  of  change  compared  with  timing  of   postdepression  peak, 

1936  to  1938 221 

38.  Amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared  with  timing  of  predepres- 

sion peak 222 

39.  Amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared  with  timing  of  depregpion 

low,  1932  to  1934 223 

40.  Frequency  of  change  compared  with  change  per  change 224 

41.  Amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared  with  change  per  change,..       225 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS  XI 

Page 

42.  Peak  month,   1929  to  1931,  compared  with  average  change  (index 

points)  per  change,  January  1926  to  April  1929 226 

43.  Frequency  of  change  compared  with  aggregate  change  less  net  change.  _       227 

44.  Amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared  with  aggregate  change  less 

net  change 228 

45.  Distribution  of  commodities  according  to  differences  in  rank  under 

various  criteria  of  wholesale  price  fl exibility 228 

46-68.  Correlation  tables  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their 

ranks  by  two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 229-241 

46.  Frequency  of  change,  1926  to  1929,  compared  with  frequency  of  change, 

1926  to  1933_._. 229 

47-48.  Two  measures  of  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared 230-231 

49.  Amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared  with  change  per  change 232 

50-51.  Two  measures  of  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared 233-234 

52-53.  Frequency  of  change  compared  with  amplitude  of  cyclical  move- 
ment   235-236 

54.  Frequency  of  change  compared  with  timing  of  predepression  peak, 

1929to  1931 237 

55.  Frequency  of  change  compared  with  change  per  change 238 

56.  Frequency  of  change  compared  with  aggregate  change  less  net  change.  239 

57.  Amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared  with  aggregate  change  less 

net  change 240 

58.  Change  per  change  compared  with  aggregate  change  less  net  change.  _       241 

59.  Distribution  of  retail  prices  of  girdles,  foundation  garments,  and  bras- 

sieres   244 

60.  Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  wash  frocks 245 

61.  Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  women's  medium-quality  dresses 246 

62.  Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  women's  cheap  dresses 246 

63.  Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  girls'  cotton  dresses 247 

64.  Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  women's  hose .. 247 

65.  Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  girls'  anklets 247 

66.  Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  men's  work  shirts 248 

67.  Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  printed  percales 249 

PART  II 

TABLES 

1.  Geographic  price  structures  for  selected  chemicals,  summarized 321 

2.  Zone  prices  and  zone  differentials — selected  chemicals 322 

3.  Prices  of  electric  refrigerators 337 

PART  III 

TABLES 

1.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  analgesic  tablets,  June  1929  to 

June  1939 356 

2.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  drug  sundry,   March  1935  to 

March  1939 358 

3.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  shaving  article,  March  1935  to 

March  1939 359 

4.  Retail   prices    of    nationally    advertised    dentifrice,    March    1935   to 

March  1939 359 

5.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  liquid  laxative,  March  1935  to 

March  1939 359 

6.  Retail  prices  of  standard  liquid  liaxative,  July  1936  to  March  1939 360 

7.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  analgesic  tablet,  June  1929  to 

March  1939 362 

8.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  drug  sundry,   March  1935  to 

March  1939 362 

9.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  shaving  article,  March  1935  to 

March  1939 363 

10.  Retail   prices    of    nationally    advertised    dentifrice,    March    1935   to 

March  1939 363 

11.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  liquid  laxative,  March  1935  to 

March  1939 _ 364 


XII  TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 

Pago 

12.  Retail  prices  of  standard  liquid  laxative,  July  1936  to  March  1939 365 

13.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  analgesic  tablets 366 

14.  Retail  prices  of  a  drug  sundry 366 

15.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  shaving  article 367 

16.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  dentifrice 367 

17.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  liquid  laxative 367 

18.  Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  cold  remedy 368 

19.  Retail  prices  of  analgesic  tablets,   nationally  advertised  brand  and 

substitute  brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores — June  1939 371 

Retail  prices  of  drug  sundry,  nationally  advertised  brand  and  substi- 
tute brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores — June  1939 372 

Retail  prices  of  shaving  article,  nationally  advertised  brand  and  substi- 
tute brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores — June  1939 372 

Retail  prices  of  liquid  laxative  "A,"  nationally  advertised  brand  and 

substitute  brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores — June  1939 373 

Retail  prices  of  cold  remedy,  nationally  advertised  brand  and  substi- 
tute brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores — June  1939 373 

Retail  prices  of  vitamin  product,  nationally  advertised  brand  and  sub- 
stitute brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores — June  1939 374 

Retail  prices  of  liquid  laxative  "B,"  nationally  advertised  brand  and 

substitute  brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores — June  1939 374 

Retail  prices  of  oral  antiseptic,  nationally  advertised  brand  and  sub- 
stitute brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores,  June  1939 375 

Retail  prices  of  ahalgesic  tablets,   nationally   advertised  brand  and 

distributors'  brands  charged  by  two  mail  order  houses 376 

Retail  prices  of  a  drug   sundry,   nationally   advertised    brand    and 

distributors'  brands,  charged  by  two  mail  order  houses 377 

Retail  prices  of  liquid  laxative  "A,"  nationally  advertised  brand  and 

distributors'  brands,  charged  by  two  mail  order  houses 377 

Retail  prices  of  liquid  laxative  "B,"  nationally  advertised  brand  and 

distributors'  brands,  charged  by  two  mail  order  houses 378 

Retail  prices  of  liquid  laxative  "A,"  nationally  advertised  and  substi- 
tute brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores — June  1939 379 

32.  Comparison  of  full  list  prices  with  contractual  minimum  prices 383 

33.  Distribution  of  retail  prices  quoted  by  drug  stores  for  13  items  selling 

between  10  and  50  pents 385 

34.  Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationallv  advertised  pharmaceutical 

"A" - ---       390 

35.  Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationally  advertised  pharmaceutical 

"B" 392 

36.  Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationally  advertised  drug  sundry 393 

37.  Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationally  advertised  toiletry  "A" 395 

38.  Wliolesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationally  advertised  toiletry  "B" 396 

39.  Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  a  nationally  advertised  toiletry  "C"..       397 

40.  Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  rationally  advertised  cosmetic  "A"..       398 

41.  Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationallv  advertised  cosmetic  "B"._       399 

42.  Terms  of  sale  for  cosmetic  "C" . 400 

43.  Wholesale  and  retail  mark-ups  for  8  nationally  advertised  products.       401 

44.  Maximum  and  minimum  retail  mark-ups  for  132  products  sold  by  a 

large  drug  manufacturer — group  I 403 

45.  Maximum  and  minimum  retail  mark-ups  for  28  products  sold  by  a 

large  drug  manufacturer — group  II ^ 403 

46.  Maximum  and  minimum    retail    mark-ups  allowed  by   12  cosmetic 

manufacturers  on  their  varicus  price  lines 404 

47.  Retail  margins  on  products  in  the  drug  trade  in  California  under  the 

California  fair  trade  law,  July  1936 ^ 405 

48.  Minimum    retail    margins    on  selected  well-known    advertised    drug 

products  in  California  under  the  California  fair  trade  law,  July  1936.       406 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


XIII 


PART  I 


CHARTS 

Page 
I.  sensitive  and  insensitive  prices.     Supported  by  statistical  data  on 

p.  2')2  in  appendix  III . 24 

II.  Wholesale  prices  of  selected  commodities:  Eggs,  cotton  goods,  and 

rayon.     Supported  by  statistical  data  on  p.  253  in  appendix  III.         25 

III.  Wholesale  prices  of  selected  commodities:  Phosphate  rock,  anthra- 

cite,  potatoes,  potash  salts,  and  electric   refrigerators.     Sup- 
ported by  statistical  data  on  pp.  254-255  in  appendix  III 26 

IV.  Change  in  average  wholesale  price  and  quantity  available  for  con- 

sumption,   111    commodities — 1929    to    1933.     Supported    by 

statistical  data  on  pp.  255-256  in  appendix  III 39 

V.  Farm  products:  Prices  and  production.     Supported  by  statistical 

data  on  p.  256  in  appendix  III 41 

VI.  Wholesale  prices  of  30  basic  commodities,  industrial  production  and 
reciprocals  of  price  dispersion.     Supported  by  statistical  data  on 

p.  257  in  appendix  III 44 

VII.  Indexes  of  wholesale  price  dispersion  and  industrial  production. 

Supported  by  statistical  data  on  p.  258  in  appendix  III 46 

VIII.  Automobile  tires:  Wholesale  price  and  average  life  of  automobile 

tires.     Supported  by  statistical  data  on  p.  258  in  appendix  III_         65 
IX.  Retail  prices  of  men's  dress  shirts.     Supported  by  statistical  data 

on  p.  259  in  appendix  III . 84 

X.  Breakfast  cereals:  Prices  and  margins.     Supported  by  statistical 

data  on  p.  259  in  appendix  III 85 

XI.  Wholesale  prices  of  selected  foods  (products  classified  into  quartiles 
according  to  consumer  buying  habits).     Supported  by  statistical 

data  on  pp.  259-260  in  appendix  III 87 

XII.  Electric  refrigerators:  Number  sold  and  retail  value;  average  reali- 
zation at  retail  and  wholesale  price  index.  Supported  by  statis- 
tical data  on  p.  261  in  appendix  III 113 

XIII.  Electric  washing  machines :  Number  sold  and  retail  value ;  average 

realization  at  retail  and  wholesale  price  index.     Supported  by 
statistical  data  on  p.  261  in  appendix  III 114 

XIV,  Vacuum  cleaners:  Number  sold  and  retail  value;  average  realiza- 

tion at  retail  and  wholesale  price  index.     Supported  by  statistical 

data  on  p.  261  in  appendix  III 115 

XV.  Electric  ranges:  Number  sold  and  retail  value;  average  realization 
at  retail  and  wholesale  price  index.  Supported  by  statistical 
data  on  p.  262  in  appendix  III ■ 116 

XVI.  Sales  and  saturation:  Electric  refrigerators,  vacuum  cleaners, 
power  washing  machines,  and  electric  ranges.     Supported  by 

statistical  data  on  p.  262  in  appendix  III 119 

XVII.  Household  equipment  ownership  by  income  groups,  electric  refrig- 
erators, 1935-36.     Supported  by  statistical  data  on  p.  263  in 

appendix  III 122-123 

XVIII.  Household  equipment  ownership  by  income  groups,  power  washing 
machines,  1935-36.  Supported  by  statistical  data  on  p.  263  in 
appendix  III 124-125 

XIIX.  Household  equipment  ownership  by  income  groups,  vacuum 
cleaners,  1935-36.     Supported  by  statistical  data  on  p.  263  in 

appendix  III 126-127 

XX.  Household  equipment  ownership  by  income  groups,  radios,  1935- 

36.     Supported  by  statistical  data  on  p.  264  in  appendix  III. .    128-129 

XXI.  Income  residuals  after  primary  expenditures  by  income  groups, 
1935-36.  Supported  by  statistical  data  on  p.  265  in  appendix 
III 132-133 


LETTER  OF  TRANSMITTAL 


U.  S.  Department  of  Labor, 
Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics, 

Washington,  June  20,  1940. 
Hon.  Joseph  C.  O'Mahoney, 

Chairman,  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee, 

United  States  Senate,  Washington,  D.  C. 

My  Dear  Senator:  I  wish  to  submit  for  the  record  this  study  of 
Price  Behavior  and  Business  Policy,  which  has  been  prepared  by  the 
staff  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  for  the  Temporary_  National 
Economic  Committee.  It  is  intended  primarily  as  a  background  for 
the  deliberations  of  the  Committee  on  matters  where  prices  are  in- 
volved. Most  of  the  report  was  written  when  our  attention  was 
focused  on  peacetime  conditions.  Although  it  considers  price  prob- 
lems in  a  peacetime  economy,  it  provides  several  guideposts  for  legis- 
lative policy — guideposts  which,  it  should  be  noted,  are  equally  ap- 
plicable in  the  midst  of  mobilizing  our  resources  for  a  great  defense 
program  or  even  in  wartime. 

It  is  a  major  objective  of  our  national  policy  to  keep  the  American 
economy  on  as  even  a  keel  as  possible  in  order  to  sustain  production 
and  employment.  In  attaining  this  objective,  whecher  in  peacetime 
or  in  wartime,  prices  play  an  all-important  role  as  a  kind  of  economic 
governor,  like  the  governor  on  an  engine.  If  any  change  is  made  in 
the  governor,  it  affects  the  operation  of  the  engine — it  may  speed  it 
up,  slow  it  down,  or  interfere  in  a  variety  of  ways  with  its  efficient 
operation. 

This  report  illustrates,  first,  the  variety  of  outside  forces  which 
affect  this  governor  of  the  economic  system,  because  of  the  great 
variety  of  market  situations  which  confront  American  business  and 
the  many  different  ways  in  which  changes  in  prices  affect  the  internal 
operations  of  industry — in  particular,  production  and  employment. 
This  analysis  suggests  the  following  guides  to  policy: 

If  any  action  is  taken  to  influence  or,  more  important,  to  regulate 
prices,  any  such  action,  to  be  successful,  must  allow  a  wide  degree  of 
flexibility  and  permit  variation  between  industries  and  between 
products.  It  is  dangerous  to  assume  that  a  single  price  policy  can 
have  universal  application.     It  clearly  cannot. 

Further,  any  agency  charged  with  influencing  or  regulating  prices 
cannot  confine  its  attention  to  prices  alone,  since  prices  are  an  integral 
part  of  the  industrial  mechanism.  Responsibility  for  marketing,  for 
production,  and  for  employment  is  implied  in  responsibility  for  prices. 

This  study  also  suggests  that  industry  can  accomplish  a  great  deal 
toward  conscious  improvemont  of  its  operations  by  d^irect  and  un- 
biased analysis  of  its  price  and  marketing  problems.  Some  of  the 
:broad  pricing  problems  confronting  business  are  illustrated  by  the 


XVI  LETTER  OP  TRANSMITTAL 

recent  history  of  a  number  of  industries  manufacturing  electrical 
household  equipment  which,  after  a  phenomenal  expansion  during  the 
last  15  years,  appeared  in  1939  to  have  reached  a  point  of  near- 
saturation  of  their  markets  in  the  upper  and  middle  income  groups. 
They  may  follow  one  of  two  courses:  Reduce  prices  and  thus  enlarge 
their  markets  in  the  lower  income  groups,  or  gear  production  largely 
for  replacement  and  assume  that  families  with  low  incomes  will  rely 
on  the  used-model  market.  Recent  (1940)  developments  in  the  elec- 
trical refrigerator  industry  suggest  that  if  less  expensive  models  are 
introduced  and  sales  of  those  models  are  pushed,  the  market  will 
broaden  and  the  volume  of  production  and  employment  can  be  main- 
tained or  increased. 

Another  major  objective  of  our  national  policy  is  to  maintain  and 
increase  America's  standard  of  living.  To  do  this  requires  not  only 
the  smooth  functioning  of  production  but  also  the  steady  flow  of 
goods  to  the  ultimate  consumer,  at  prices  at  which  they  can  be  sold 
m  volume.  Here,  again,  the  level  of  retail  prices  is  the  key  to  the 
situation.  Prices,  in  their  turn,  are  influenced  by  the  nature  of  retail 
markets  and  the  margin  which  distributors  require.  Attention  in  the 
field  of  prices  has  hitherto  been  limited  largely  to  wholesale  prices. 
In  our  opinion,  msufficient  attention  has  been  given  to  retail  prices 
paid  by  the  ultimate  consumer. 

This  report  indicates  that  there  are  certain  important  rigidities  in 
retail  prices,  which  prevent  them  from  being  reduced  freely,  and  to 
which  this  Committee  may  well  direct  its  attention.  I  refer  to  the 
so-called  fair-trade  laws  which  have  been  enacted  by  44  States  and 
to  the  Miller-Tydings  Enabling  Act  which  legalizes  resfile  price  main- 
tenance contracts  in  interstate  commerce.  I  refer  also  to  the  Unfair 
Practices  Acts  which  are  on  the  statute  books  of  about  half  the  States 
and  which,  while  purporting  merely  to  prohibit  sales  below  cost,  seem 
to  lend  themselves  to  highly  restrictive  activities.  Further,  in  some 
lines  of  trade,  particularly  certain  drugs,  there  appear  to  be  unduly 
wide  margins  between  the  cost  of  ingredients,  the  sale  price  at  whole- 
sale, and  the  price  to  the  consumer. 

This  report  shows  that  in  recent  years,  both  in  wholesale  and  retail 
markets,  businessmen  have  more  and  more  preferred  to  base  sales 
appeal  on  factors  other  than  price,  such  as  quality,  style,  appearance, 
advertising,  brand  names,  and  trade-marks.  This  trend  limits  still 
further  the  effectiveness  of  any  form  of  regulation  dealing  with  prices 
directly.  At  the  same  time,  it  makes  it  imperative  that  the  consumer 
should  be  given  every  opportunity  to  know  exactly  what  it  is  that  he 
is  buying;  that  ho  should  be  afforded  every  facility  to  learn  wiiat  a 
can  of  food  contains  or  what  fabric  has  gone  into  a  garment.  Con- 
sumer education  and  clearer  standards  for  consumers'  goods  are  im- 
portant in  order  that  the  American  public  may  be  put  in  a  position 
to  expend  its  purchasing  power  wisely,  an  end  whicii  is  desirable  both 
from  the  point  of  view  of  the  standard  of  living  of  the  people  and 
the  maximum  employment  of  men  and  materials 

This  report  consists  of  three  parts.  Part  I  is  a  general  description 
of  various  aspects  of  business  price  policy  and  of  their  consequences 
to  the  economy.  Part  11  is  a  detailed  description  of  one  phase  of 
business  price  policy;  namely,  geographic  price  structures,  such  as 
basing  point  systems,  zoning  systems,  and  the  like.     Part  III  is  a 


LETTER  OF  TRANSMITTAL  XVII 

discussion  of  retail  prices  with  concrete  analysis  of  distributive  margins 
in  the  drug  industry. 

Much  of  the  information  upon  which  this  report  is  based  was  com- 
piled from  published  and  unpublished  data  in  the  files  of  the  Bureau 
of  Labor  Statistics.  In  addition,  extensive  information  was  available 
in  various  publications,  including  those  prepared  by  other  Govern- 
ment agencies.  The  study  of  the  electrical  equipment  industries  is 
based  largely  on  a  field  survey  by  representatives  of  the  Bureau  and 
was  made  possible  by  the  cooperation  of  leading  manufacturers  and 
distributors. 

These  studies  of  prices  were  prepared  under  the  general  direction 
of  Aryness  Joy,  assistant  to  the  Commissioner  of  Labor  Statistics  and 
director  of  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  Studies  for  the 
Bureau,  Edward  S.  Mason,  professor  of  economics  at  Harvard  Uni- 
vei*sity,  has  served  as  economic  consultant  iiT  their  planning.  This 
monograph  was  written  by  Saul  Nelson  and  Walter  G.  Keim,  with 
the  assistance  of  Laura  Mae  Brown,  John  M.  Blair,  and  William  C. 
French,  Jr. 

There  follows,  for  the  convenience  of  the  Committee,  three  brief 
but  somewhat  more  extensive  summaries  describing  the  matters  dealt 
with  in  parts  I,  IF,  and  III,  respectively. 

Respectfully  submitted. 

ISADOR  LUBIN, 

Commissioner  of  Labor  Statistics 


247149—41 — No.  1- 


SUMMARY 

Part  I — Price  Behavior  and  Business  Policy 

Part  I  of  this  report  on  Price  Behavior  and  Business  Policy  is  con- 
cerned broadly  with  the  way  in  which  the  poHcy  decisions  of  business- 
men in  the  field  of  price  affect  the  functioning  of  the  economy.  It  was 
not  primarily  designed  to  present  specific  legislative  recommendations 
but  rather  to  present  factual  background  and  to  serve  as  a  guide  to 
policy.  .It  is  evident  from  the  analysis  that  no  simple  single  approach 
to  prices  as  such  will  solve  the  problem  of  increasing  and  maintaining 
industrial  activity.    The  problem  is  far  too  complex. 

Part  I  is  concerned  with  two  fundamental  issues.  The  first  is  the 
problem  of  price  flexibility,  which  arises  from  the  tendency  of  the 
prices  of  some  commodities,  notably  farm  products,  to  fluctuate  far 
more  freely  and  frequently  than  the  prices  of  others.  The  effect  of 
these  discrepancies  upon  the  course  of  business  activity  and  employ- 
ment has  been  a  subject  of  much  controversy.  The  second  concerns 
the  efforts  of  businessmen  to  direct  competitive  effort  into  channels 
other  than  price,  a  trend  which  has  had  important  effects  upon  the 
economy.  Following  the  general  discussion  of  these  issues,  market 
trends  in  some  of  the  electrical  household  equipment  industries  are 
appraised  as  affording  concrete  illustrations  of  many  of  the  policy 
problems  confronting  business  concerns  and  the  economic  implications 
of  their  decisions.  Part  I  also  includes  three  appendices,  largely 
statistical  in  content,  bearing  upon  the  same  issues. 

The  body  of  the  report  consists  of  the  following  four  chapters: 

Chapter  I.  Price  Behavior  and  Business  Policy. — In  the  everyday 
conduct  of  their  affairs,  businessmen  are  constantly  required  to  make 
decisions  regarding  their  sales  policies;  that  is  to  determine  the 
character  and  variety  of  the  goods  which  they  are  to  produce,  the 
price  and  other  terms  and  conditions  under  which  the  goods  are  to  be 
offered  for  sale,  and  the  type  of  sales  appeal  which  can  most  effectively 
be  used  in  finding  a  market.  These  decisions  in  the  aggregate  have  a 
far-reaching  effect  upon  the  national  economy. 

Commodity  prices  are  to  varying  degrees  influenced  by  day-to-day 
decisions  of  this  kind.  The  prices  of  most  farm  products  and  of  some 
industrial  commodities  are  arrived  at  in  markets  where  so  manj^ 
buyers  and  sellers  operate  that  no  one  buyer  or  seller  has  any  appreci- 
able influence  on  the  resulting  price.  In  the  case  of  most  manufactured 
goods  and  some  raw  materials,  the  situation  is  quite  different.  The 
manuf6,cturer  of  steel,  of  automobiles,  of  corn  flakes  or  of  proprietary 
drugs,  for  example,  has  a  very  real  voice  in  deciding  the  price  at  which 
he  will  sell.  No  concern  has  unlimited  latitude  in  determining  price 
poHcy;  even  a  monopolist  must  reckon  with  the  competition  of  sub- 
stitute products.  In  general,  the  amount  of  discretion  available  to 
any  business  concern  in  setting  prices  depends  upon  many  factors, 
fiuch  as  the  nature  of  its  product,  the  availability  of  satisfactory 

XIX 


XX  SUMMARY 

substitutes,  the  number  and  size  of  its  compeUtors_  and  its  relations 
with  them,  and  the  impact  of  law  and  administrative  governmental 
action. 

In  this  respect,  concerns  selling  articles  which  are  in  fact  different 
or  which  consumers  believe  to  be  different  from  those  sold  by  their 
competitors  are  at  a  distinct  advantage  over  those  whose  products  are 
in  all  respects  standard.  For  example,  it  is  obviously  impossible  for 
a  single  seller  of  such  commodities  as  iron  ore,  copper  ingot,  or  sulfuric 
acid  to  maintain  for  any  appreciable  period  of  time  a  price  substan- 
tially different  from  that  quoted  by  all  other  sellers  in  the  same  market. 
On  the  other  hand,  where  buyei"s  for  any  reason  prefer  the  products  of 
one  seller  to  those  of  another,  they  will  be  willing  to  pay  some  premium. 
It  is  not  essential  that  such  differences  represent  intrinsic  physical  dif- 
ferences of  utilities;  the  important  point  is  the  buyer's  psychological 
appraisal,  the  beliej  that  a  difference  exists  which  makes  one  product 
more  desirable  than  another.  If  a  product  has  acquired  outstanding 
prestige,  it  is  unnecessary  for  its  producer  to  follow  all  the  ups  and 
downs  of  the  general  market.  In  such  fields  as  packaged  medicines, 
where  it  is  particularly  difficult  for  the  average  buyer  intelligently  to 
compare  the  merits  of  similar  products,  wide  differences  in  price  are 
maintained  for  long  periods  of  time  between  merchandise  which  is 
virtually  identical  in  all  but  name. 

Because  of  the  close  relationship  between  prices  and  profits,  busi- 
nessmen are  traditionally  eager  to  exercise  a  substantial  degree  of  con- 
trol over  the  prices  of  their  products.  In  addition  they  usually  favor 
price  stability  as  a  means  of  facilitating  business  planning.  Price 
stability  may  be  achieved  in  many  ways.  Within  limits  and  for  cer- 
tain products  it  may  be  attained  by  emphasizing  quality,  services, 
brand  names,  advertising,  etc.  But  the  accentuation  of  product  dif- 
ferences cannot  of  itself  shield  any  concern  completely  from  price  com- 
petition and  there  are  many  markets  in  which  it  is  not  applicable. 
Consequently,  more  direct  schemes  to  achieve  control  over  prices  re- 
main common.  These  devices  includ(;  price  leadership,  conventional 
arrangements  within  an  industry  such  as  basing-point  systems,  uniform 
cost-accounting  systems,  patent  pools,  restrictive  patent  licensing,  and 
outright  collusion. 

Chapter  II.  Price  Flexibility. — The  techniques  described  above  have 
made  the  prices  of  many  products  relatively  stable.  On  the  other 
hand,  there  are  many  business  concerns  which  make  no  effort  to  avoid 
price  competition  and  there  are  many  markets  which  cannot  be  effec- 
tively controlled.  Partly  as  a  result  of  this  situation,  there  are  wide 
differences  between  the  price  behavior  of  different  commodities;  some 
change  infrequently  and  narrowly,  others  move  more  freely  and  widely. 
These  discrepancies  are  particularly  evident  during  periods  of  economic 
upheaval.  During  the  1929-33  depression,  for  example,  while  the 
prices  of  such  products  as  copper  and  hides  showed  extreme  declines 
of  over  70  percent,  the  prices  of  other  items  such  as  agricultural  imple- 
ments and  anthracite  coal  scarcely  fell  at  all.  This  tendency  of  some 
prices  to  be  flexible  and  others  to  be  relatively  "rigid"  raises  the  first 
basic  issue  with  which  the  report  is  concerned.  Although  flexibility 
relates  to  periods  of  upturn  as  well  as  those  of  do^^•ntu^n,  it  is  the  latter 
aspect  which  has  received  most  attention  in  recent  years  and  which  is 
accordingly  empha.sized  in  this  report. 


SUMMAR1  XXI 

While  these  differences  in  price  behavior  are  in  no  sense  new,  there 
is  evidence  that  the  far-reaching  teciinological  and  other  changes  of 
recent  years  combined  have  materially  altered  the  structure  of  many 
markets  and  that  as  a  result  inflexible  prices  play  a  somewhat  more 
important  role  in  the  economy  today  than  was  true  too,  generations  ago. 

It  has  been  argued  that  the  decline  of  production  and  employment 
in  many  lines  during  the  downturn  of  1929-33  would  have  been  less 
drastic  if  price  readjustments  had  been  greater.  Although  this  is  no 
doubt  true  in  certain  cases,  the  relationship  existing  between  price 
and  production  for  any  specific  commodity  is  extremely  complex  and 
it  is  unlikely  that  uniform  flexibility  of  prices,  even  if  it  were  attain- 
able, would  itself  turn  the  tide  of  depression  and  bring  about  recovery. 
Prompter  readjustments  during  the  initial  phases  of  a  business  de- 
cline might  retard  the  downturn,  but  the  effect  of  practicable  price 
reductions  after  the  recession  has  become  pronounced  is  clearly 
limited. 

It  is  particularly  important  to  recognize  that  any  appraisal  of  this 
issue  of  price  sensitivity  must  consider  the  economy  as  an  interde- 
pendent whole.  The  effects  of  price  changes  must  be  considered  in 
combination  with  each  other  and  with  the  behavior  of  noncommodity 
prices  such  as  services,  rents,  wages,  interest  rates,  and  taxes,  as 
well. 

Moreover,  wholesale  commodity  prices  are  only  part  of  the  picture. 
Prices  paid  by  ultimate  consumers  are  often  the  key  to  whether  sales 
and  hence  production  and  employment  increase.  It  is  well  known 
that  price  movements  on  retail  markets  are  usually  narrower  than  at 
the  wholesale  level.  Moreover,  any  policy  looking  toward  increasing 
the  flexibility  of  wholesale  prices  as  a  means  of  achieving  recovery 
would  be  of  very  limited  value  if  at  the  same  time  the  rigidity  of 
retail  prices  is  increased  by  the  enactment  of  such  legislation  as  the 
so-called  Fair  Trade  Acts. 

It  is  apparent  that  the  problem  of  price  flexibihty  will  not  yield  to 
any  simple  solution.  No  common  remedy  to  induce  gTeater  flexi- 
bility in  price — were  that  clearly  desirable — can  be  devised.  How- 
ever, there  is  little  doubt  that  rigid  prices  which  are  maintained  at 
unduly  high  levels  through  collusive  restraints  of  trade  impair  the 
functioning  of  the  economy,  and  that  insistence  upon  certain  broad 
standards  of  business  conduct  such  as  those  prescribed  in  the  anti- 
trust laws  may  constitute  a  distinct  step  toward  the  achievement  of 
the  goal  of  sustained  employment  and  production. 

Chapter  III.  Nori'price  Competition. — Since  differences  in  consumer 
acceptance  yield  individual  concerns  a  distinct  degree  of  freedom  in 
determining  the  price  of  their  products,  it  is  not  surprising  that  there 
should  be  constant  efforts  to  create  or  accentuate  such  differences 
through  emphasis  upon  such  elements  as  quality,  performance,  and 
style,  supplemented  by  the  use  of  trade-marks,  brands,  and  adver- 
tising. There  is  today  a  widespread  belief  in  business  circles  that 
competitive  efforts  should  be  directed  toward  these  nonprice  aspects 
of  competition  almost  to  the  exclusion  of  price,  that  sales  campaigns 
should  emphasize  quality,  service,  and  performance  and  should  avoid 
price  cutting  as  a  competitive  technique.  This  raises  the  second 
basic  issue  treated  in  the  report. 

It  seems  reasonably  clear  that  the  change  in  competitive  emphasis 
has  not  been  entirely  undesirable.     Thus  it  is  probably  true  that  the 


XXII  SUMMARY 

increased  attention  paid  to  quality  and  performance  has  served  to 
stimulate  technical  research.  Certainly  the  automobile,  the  refrig- 
erator, and  the  tractor  are  more  satisfactory  products  today  than 
they  were  some  years  ago.  Undoubtedly  technical  advances  would 
have  occurred  even  if  competition  focused  upon  price,  but  it  is  at 
least  arguable  that  centering  attention  upon  quality  stimulated  its 
improvement.  Conversely,  there  is  some,  evidence  that  excessive 
emphasis  upon  price  may  lead  at  times  to  undesirable  degradation  of 
quality. 

On  the  other  hand  it  must  be  recognized  that  emphasis  upon 
quality  has  often  served  to  divert  eflFort  from  programs  designed  to 
produce  cheap  but  satisfactory  merchandise  to  meet  the  needs  of 
lower  income  groups.  It  has  been  argued,  for  example,  that  the  pro- 
duction of  cheaper  automobiles  or  refrigerators,  stripped  of  all  luxury 
features,  could  serve  a  useful  purpose  in  expanding  the  potential  mar- 
ket for  these  products. 

One  of  the  most  serious  objections  to  many  forms  of  nonprice  com- 
petition is  the  manner  in  which  they  complicate  the  buyer's  problems 
of  selection.  Price  is  a  universal  measure  and  the  significance  of  a 
price  difference  is  readily  imderstood  by  any  buyer.  The  appraisal  of 
differences  in  content  or  quality,  or  the  translation  of  collateral  terms 
of  sale  into  price  equivalents,  is  much  more  diflficult,  particularly  for 
the  average  untrained  consumer.  Consequently,  when  the  policy  of 
distinguishing  one's  product  from  a  competitor's  is  revealed  not  in 
any  real  betterment  of  quality  but  in  the  multiplication  of  unneeded 
gadgets  and  superficial  eyecatchiug  features,  there  may  be  a  distinct 
loss  of  competitive  efficiency. 

When  price  competition  is  suppressed  through  collusive  or  coercive 
tactics  it  seems  particularly  pernicious,  judged  by  any  social  or  eco- 
nomic standards.  All  these  schemes  have  the  disadvantage  of  sub- 
stituting for  a  direct  price  cut,  which  the  consumer  wants  and  can 
measure,  some  substitute  of  uncertain  value  which  he  may  well  forego. 
If  but  a  small  fraction  of  these  economically  useless  expenditures  were 
translated  into  reductions  in  the  price  level,  the  gain  in  public  pur- 
chasing power  and  the  resulting  stimulus  to  production  and  employ- 
ment might  be  material. 

Chapter  IV.  The  Electrical  Equipment  Industries — An  Illustrative 
Case. — The  recent  history  of  a  number  of  industries  manufacturing 
electrical  household  equipment  such  as  refrigerators,  washing  ma- 
chines, and  vacuum  cleaners  presents  a  number  of  these  policy  issues 
in  concrete  terms.  These  are  all  relatively  new  industries  which  have 
experienced  their  major  growth  during  the  past  two  decades.  Until 
recently  their  sales  problems  have  been  simple.  Their  sales  were 
constantly  expanding  under  the  influence  of  improved  technology 
and  lower  prices.  By  1939,  however,  the  market  for  original  equip- 
ment among  the  upper  and  middle  income  groups  had  become  largely 
saturated  while  prices  had  not  yet  been  reduced  to  a  level  at  which 
members  of  the  lower  income  groups  could  participate  actively  in  the 
market  for  new  equipment.  The  consequences  of  this  situation  were 
illustrated  by  an  abrupt  fall  in  the  sales  of  electric  refrigerators  dur- 
ing the  1937-38  recession  in  contrast  to  the  relative  stability  of  sales 
between  1929  and  1933. 


SUMMAKY  KXIII 

During  1939,  therefore,  manufacturers  of  these  products  were  faced 
with  the  need  for  reorienting  sales  policies  to  meet  these  changing  con- 
ditions. Two  avenues  of  sales  expansion  were  possible;  development 
of  the  replacement  market  among  consumers  who  had  already  pur- 
chased equipment  together  with  improved  facilities  for  the  resale  of 
used  equipment  taken  in  trade,  and  expansion  of  the  market  among 
those  consumers  who  had  previously  been  unable  to  afford  to  buy. 
At  the  time  this  report  was  being  prepared  (in  the  autumn  of  1939), 
it  was  suggested  that  these  ends  might  be  achieved  by  price  reductions 
based  partly  upon  economies  of  manufacture,  but  more  importantly, 
upon  a  less  costly  system  of  distribution  and  also  by  the  development 
of  a  coordinated  policy  for  handling  trade-in  equipment  on  replace- 
ment sales. 

Since  the  beginning  of  1940,  the  refrigerator  manufacturers,  at 
least,  have  begun  to  adjust  their  policies  along  th-se  lines.  Prices, 
which  were  changed  but  little  between  1933  and  1937,  have  been 
sharply  reduced  for  certain  models  of  medium  size;  economies  have 
been  sought  in  both  manufacture  and  distribution  and,  it  is  reported, 
sales  are  running  above  those  of  last  year.  These  developments 
clearly  indicate  the  possibility  of  expansion  in  production  and  em- 
ployment through  the  reconsideration  of  business  sales  policies,  and 
emphasize  the  need  for  common  consideration  of  problems  of  this 
character  by  business  and  government. 

Appendix  I  presents  a  number  of  different  measures  of  price  flexi- 
bility which  have  been  developed  to  assist  research  in  that  field. 

Appendix  II  is  a  detailed  treatment  of  one  phase  of  nonprice  compe- 
tition ;  the  observance  of  so-called  price  lines  in  the  markets  for  many 
consumer  goods. 

Appendix  III  includes  the  statistical  tables  supporting  the  several 
charts  presented  in  part  I. 

Part  II — Geographic  Price  Structures 

Part  II  of  the  report  on  Price  Behavior  and  Business  Policy  treats 
one  specific  aspect  of  business  price  policy.  It  consists  of  a  descrip- 
tion of  geographic  price  structures  for  a  wide  variety  of  commodities; 
that  is,  of  the  way  in  which  the  delivered  prices  of  these  commodities 
vary  from  point  to  point  in  relation  to  differences  in  the  costs  of  ship- 
ping the  product  from  its  origin  to  its  destination. 

In  the  sale  of  most  commodities,  conventional  practices  have  devel- 
oped with  regard  to  the  manner  in  which  freight  charges  are  related  to 
the  delivered  price.  Some  sellers  maintain  a  uniform  price  at  their 
plants  to  all  buyers  regardless  of  their  location.  Others  quote  uni- 
form delivered  prices  in  all  markets  or  within  defined  geographic  zones. 
Still  others  vary  their  prices  systematically  or  unsystematically  in 
order  to  meet  or  undersell  their  rivals  in  all  markets  in  which  they  wish 
to  do  business.  Some  of  these  practices,  notably  basing-point  systems 
and  zone  systems,  may  result  in  greatly  limiting  or  eliminating  price 
competition  in  the  markets  for  the  commodities  affected. 

These  types  of  geographic  price  structure,  particularly  the  basing- 
point  system,  have  consequently  been  the  subject  of  much  controversy 
in  discussions  of  the  problems  of  monopoly  and  competition  in  indus- 


XXIV  SUMMABY 

trial  markets.  Legislation  has  been  proposed  to  the  Congress  which 
would  have  the  effect  of  prohibiting  the  use  of  basing-point  systems. 
There  has  not  been,  however,  any  general  survey  of  the  extent  to 
which  different  types  of  geographic  price  structures  are  actually  en- 
countered in  the  American  economy,  nor  of  the  considerations  which 
favor  the  development  of  one  or  another  type  of  practice.  Such 
information  seems  needed  for  an  adequate  general  appraisal  of  the 
relationship  of  basing-point  systems,  zone  systems,  aijd  other  schemes 
of  freight  equalization,  to  the  pattern  of  competition  within  an 
industry. 

Among  the  problems  with  which  the  Temporary  National  Economic 
Committee  is  immediately  confronted  is  whether  the  existing  anti- 
trust legislation  is  adequate  to  cope  with  geographic  pricing  practices 
which  may  seem  to  impair  the  efficacy  of  price  competition.  This 
volume  is  designed  to  yield  a  sunamary  of  the  facts  needed  for  a  general 
appraisal  of  these  practices  and  to  serve  as  background  for  any  legis- 
lative proposals  which  may  be  made.  It  describes  pricing  structures 
of  a  wide  variety  of  commodities,  industrial,  agricultural,  and  extrac- 
tive.    It  does  not  present  conclusions  or  recommendations. 

Pa-et  III — Prices  and  Price  Margins  in  the  Drug  Trade 

Retail  prices — the  prices  paid  by  the  ultimate  consiuner — are  of 
primary  importance  in  determining  the  standard  of  living,  the 
demand  for  goods  and  services,  and  the  amount  of  work  provided 
and  material  resources  used  in  their  production.  Retail  prices 
are  in  turn  closely  dependent  upon  distributive  margins;  that  is  upon 
the  spread  between  prices  in  wholesale  and  in  retail  markets.  Part 
III  deals  with  retail  prices  and  price  margins  for  products  handled  by 
the  drug  trade,  such  as  drugs,  toiletries,  and  drug  sundries. 

Because  of  the  difficulty  encountered  by  the  average  consumer 
in  comparing  the  merits  of  rival  drugs  and  toiletries,  competition 
between  manufacturers  has  centered  largely  upon  advertising,  trade- 
marks, and  attractive  packaging.  At  the  same  time,  it  is  to  the 
manufacturer's  advantage  to  do  all  that  he  can  to  enlist  the  active 
sales  cooperation  of  the  retailer  in  pushing  his  particular  product. 
As  a  result  many  manufacturers  have  adopted  the  policy  of  guarantee- 
ing attractive  margins  to  wholesalers  and  to  retailers  by  fixing  mini- 
mum resale  prices  for  their  products  under  the  provisions  of  state 
resale   price-mauitenance   statutes    (the    so-called    fair-trade    laws). 

Where  resale  prices  have  not  been  fixed  in  this  manner,  there  is 
usually  a  very  wide  variation  between  the  prices  charged  the  con- 
sumer by  different  druggists  for  the  same  product.  Aggressive 
price  cutting  by  some  retailers  apparently  has  had  a  tendency  to 
cause  retail  and  wholesale  prices  to  decline  over  a  period  of  years. 
The  wide  spread  between  the  prices  charged  by  the  manufacturer  of 
these  products  and  the  cost  of  their  ingredients  makes  such  progres- 
sive reductions  possible. 

Where  minimum  resale  prices  have  been  legallj^  established,  the 
prices  charged  by  different  retailers  fall  into  a  much  narrower  range 
and  in  some  cases  may  approach  complete  uniformity.  TJie  absence 
of  aggressive  price  cutting  may  also  make  it  unnecessary  for  the 
manufacturer  to  readjust  his  prices  to  progressively  lower  levels. 


SUMMARY  XXV 

The  data  indicate  that  the  prices  of  nationally  advertised  brands 
of  drugs  and  toiletries  are  usually  materially  higher  than  those  of 
virtually  identical  merchandise  which  is  tmbranded  or  which  bears  a 
distributor's  private  label. 

The  terms  under  which  manufacturers  sell  these  products  to  whole- 
salers and  under  which  drug  wholesalers  resell  to  retailers  are  often 
very  complex,  involving  various  forms  of  quantity  and  cash  dis- 
counts, free  deals,  and  advertising  allowances  which  are  illustrated 
here.  Consequently,  the  gross  margin  or  mark-up  of  the  wholesaler 
and  retailer  will  vary  not  only  for  different  kinds  of  products,  but  for 
the  same  product  depending  both  upon  the  conditions  under  which 
he  purchases  and  the  price  at  which  he  sells. 

In  general,  however, .  the  wholesaler's  gross  margin  or  mark-up 
on  the  sale  of  most  drugs,  toiletries,  and  drug  sundries  approximates 
15  percent,  while  that  of  the  retail  drug^st  approximates  33  percent 
of  their  respective  selling  prices.  Margins  are  usually  narrower  for 
popular  nationally  advertised  articles  which  are  often  used  as  price 
leaders,  and  somewhat  wider  for  slower-moving  merchandise  for  which 
prices  are  rarely  featured. 


PART  I 
PRICE  BEHAVIOR  AND  BUSINESS  POLICY 

BY 

SAUL  NELSON  and  WALTER  G.  KEIM 

ASSISTED  BY 

LAURA  MAE  BROWN  and  JOHN  M.  BLAIR 


PART  I 

PREFACE 

The  behavior  of  commodity  prices  is  of  central  importance  to  the 
fimctioning  of  the  economy  and  is  the  key  to  many  of  the  problems 
wdth  which  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  is  primarily 
concerned.  Part  I  of  this  study  of  Price  Behavior  and  Business 
Policy  comprises  a  general  analysis  of  the  relation  between  commodity 
price  behavior  and  the  policy  decisions  of  businessmen.  The  four 
chapters  consider  in  order: 

1.  Price  behavior  and  business  policy. — The  manner  in  which  the 
policy  decisions  of  businessmen  affect  the  behavior  of  commodity 
prices  and  the  character  and  variety  of  goods  produced  for  con- 
sumption. 

2.  Price  flexibility. — The  relationship  between  the  behavior  of  prices 
and  the  cyclical  upswings  and  downswings  of  business  activity,  with 
emphasis  on  the  influence  of  the  flexibility  or  rigidity  of  commodity 
prices  upon  the  level  of  employment  and  the  utilization  of  material 
resources. 

3.  Nonprice  competition. — The  extent  to  which  businessmen,  by 
their  sales  policy  decisions,  have-  directed  competitive  effort  into 
channels  other  than  price,  and  the  significance  of  various  aspects  of 
nonprice  competition  in  determining  the  general  standard  of  living. 

4.  The  electrical  equipment  industries — An  illustrative  case. — An 
analysis  of  the  conditions  influencing  the  markets  for  certain  kinds  of 
electrical  household  equipment,  as  a  specific  illustration  of  the  factors 
considered  by  businessmen  in  their  price  policy  decisions,  and  the 
consequences  of  such  decisions  to  the  economy. 

There  are  also  three  appendices,  including: 

Appendix  1.  A  detailed  presentation  of  various  measures  of  price 
flexibility  and  an  analysis  of  their  significance  and  relationships. 

Appendix  2.  A  description  of  the  practice  of  selling  by  "price  lines." 

Appendix  3.  Statistical  tables  supporting  the  charts  in  part  I  of 
the  report. 

Part  I  was  prepared  by  Saul  Nelson  and  Walter  G.  Keim,  with 
the  assistance  of  Laura  Mae  Brown,  John  M.  Blair,  and  Wilham  C. 
T'rench,  Jr.  Joseph  W.  Lethco  was  in  charge  of  the  clerical  staff  and 
Sybil  Archer  of  the  editorial  and  stenographic  staff  for  these  studies. 
Jesse  M.  Cutts  of  the  Wholesale  Price  Division  provided  much  of  the 
basic  material  and  consulted  with  the  Staff. ^ 

Chapter  IV,  dealing  with  the  electrical  appliance  industries,  could 
not  have  been  written  were  it  not  for  the  helpful  information  and 
advice  given  by  many  members  of  these  industries  and  the  materials 
provided  by  the  Bureau's  Retail  Price  Division;  the  buyers  of  various 
department  stores  located  in  Washington,  D.  C  made  available 
much  of  the  material  relating  to  "price  lines." 

>  The  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  has  prepared  for  the  use  of  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Com- 
mittee a  series  of  mimeographed  volumes  on  specifications  for  wholesale  price  m  which  list  and  describe  all 
•Of  the  wholesale  price  data  collected  by  the  Bureau.  These  volumes  proved  particularly  useful  la  the 
preparation  of  this  report. 

3 


CHAPTER  I  ' 
PRICE  BEHAVIOR  AND  BUSINESS  POLICY 

During  recent  years,  attention  has  been  focused  upon  the  behavior 
of  commodity  prices  as  constituting  at  least  one  of  the  factors  which 
contributed  to  the  unprecedented  severity  and  duration  of  the  de- 
pression which  began  in  1929,  and  of  the  persistent  failure  to  utilize 
the  Nation's  economic  resources  effectively  during  the  past  decade. 
Specifically/  it  has  been  contended  that  some  of  the  price  policies 
followed  by  businessmen  have  been  undesirable  from  the  point  of 
view  of  the  national  economy;  that  these  policies  materially  aggravated 
the  severity  of  the  downturn  between  1929  and  1933;  that  they  re- 
tarded the  pace  of  recovery  between  1933  and  1937,  and  that  they 
again  were  a  factor  in  the  recession  of  1937-38. 

The  joint  resolution  of  the  Senate  and  the  House  of  Representatives 
creating  a  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  enjoined  the 
Committee  with  the  duty  of  investigating  "the  matters  referred  to  in 
the  President's  message  of  April  29,  1938"  including,  among  others, 
"the  effect  of  the  existing  price  system  and  the  price  policies  of  in- 
dustry upon  the  general  level  of  trade,  upon  employment,  upon  long- 
term  profits,  and  upon  consumption." 

Much  of  the  problem  is  implicit  in  the  very  phrase  "price  policy." 
To  say  that  a  businessman  has  a  price  policy  necessarily  means  that 
he  has  some  degree  of  latitude  in  determining  the  prices  of  the  com- 
modities he  has  to  sell  (or  perhaps  of  those  he  wants  to  buy).  In 
many  sections  of  the  economy,  of  course,  no  such  latitude  exists.  The 
farmer,  as  an  individual,  for  example,  can  have  no  price  policy  with 
regard  to  the  wheat  or  cotton  he  produces.  He  is  so  insignificant  a 
factor  in  the  total  market  that  he  must  simply  accept  the  price  as 
he  finds  it.  The  prices  of  most  farm  products  and  of  some  industrial 
commodities,  (e.  g.,  cotton  goods)  are  arrived  at  by  the  interaction 
of  so  many  buyers  and  sellers  that  no  one  buyer  or  seller  has  any 
appreciable  influence  upon  the  result. 

In  the  case  of  most  manufactured  products  and  some  raw  materials, 
on  the  other  hand,  the  individual  businessman  can  exercise  some 
discretion  in  determming  the  price  of  his  wares.  The  manufacturer 
of  steel,  of  automobiles,  of  corn  flakes,  or  of  proprietaiy  drugs  has  a 
very  real  voice  in  deciding  the  price  at  which  he  will  sell.  The  extent 
of  this  discretion  varies  widely;  it  is  generafly,  though  not  necessarily, 
greater  where  competing  sellers  are  few  than  where  they  are  many. 
Thus,  a  manufacturer  of  milk  bottles  probably  has  substantially 
greater  control  over  the  price  of  his  product  than  does  a  producer  of 
furniture.  There  are  often  important  differences  within  any  given 
industry;  the  leading  producer  of  gypsum  plaster  may  to  a  large 
extent  control  its  price  merely  by  virtue  of  its  dominant  size,  while 
smaller  competitors  must  take  the  market  as  they  find  it.     No  con- 

'  Ch.  I  was  prepared  by  Saul  Nelson. 
,  4 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  5 

cern  has  unlimited  latitude  in  determining  price  policy;  even  a  "mo- 
nopolist" must  reckon  with  the  competition  of  substitute  products. 

For  obvious  reasons  most  business  concerns  seek  in  many  ways  to 
increase  their  degree  of  control  over  prices,  sometimes  by  methods 
which  constitute  restraint  of  trade  in  the  old-fashioned  "trust-busting" 
sense.  However,  control  may  also  be  extended  in  many  other  ways 
which  violate  neither  the  letter  nor  the  spirit  of  the  Sherman  or 
Clayton  Acts.  Far-reaching  changes  in  technology  and  in  market 
structure  during  the  past  generation  have  materially  widened  the 
area  of  discretion  available  to  individual  firms.  The  increasing  differ- 
entiation and  complexity  of  manufactured  goods  offered  for  sale, 
together  with  the  widely  expanded  influence  of  national  advertising 
have  contributed  to  this  effect.  In  many  industries,  moreover,  the 
nature  of  the  manufacturing  process  automatically  restricts  the  field 
to  huge  aggregations  of  capital  and  discourages  the  entry  of  new 
concerns.  The  effect  of  these  changes,  together  with  some  of  the 
tactics  used  by  business  concerns  in  their  efforts  to  influence  the 
movement  of  prices,  will  be  considered  below. 

However,  before  proceeding  to  such  an  analysis,  it  should  be 
emphasized  that  the  formulation  of  price  policies  (with  the  term 
"price"  used  in  its  narrow  sense)  is  only  one  phase  of  a  much  broader 
area  in  which  the  discretion  of  individual  business  concerns  may  be 
exercised.  To  look  at  price  alone  is  to  oversimplify  the  problem. 
The  character  of  the  commodity  which  is  offered  for  sale  and  all  the 
surrounding  terms  of  the  transaction  must  also  be  considered.  Price 
is  merely  a  focus  for  all  the  complex  questions  involved  in  industrial 
management  and  industrial  markets. 

In  the  automobile  industry,  for  example,  before  the  individual 
manufacturer  can  set  a  price  for  his  product,  decisions  must  be  reached 
on  many  other  points.  One  of  the  most  important  is  the  selection  of 
the  income  group  to  which  the  car  is  designed  to  appeal.  There  may 
be  an  alternative  between  improving  the  quality  of  an  automobile 
whose  retail  price  will  approximate  $700  or  $800,  or  producing  a 
much  cheaper  model  to  sell  for  $400  or  $500.  Quality  improvement, 
in  turn,  may  emphasize  performance,  or  riding  comfort,  or  appearance, 
or  possibly  the  multiplication  of  minor  eye-catching  features.  The 
practice  of  introducing  annual  model  changes  represents  an  important 
polic}'-  decision,  based  presumably  upor  the  desire  to  stimulate  fre- 
quent replacement;  it  has  been  argued  that  less  frequent  model  changes 
would  yield  manufacturing  economies  and  lower  new  car  prices, 
thereby  increasing  original  sales  at  the  possible  expense  of  retarding 
replacements.  Such  decisions  as  these  are  factors  in  setting  the 
practical  limits  within  which  prices  may  be  fixed. 

In  planning  their  general  sales  strategy,  many  concerns  face  a 
broad  choice  between  emphasis  upon  price  appeal  and  the  expenditure 
of  large  funds  for  advertising.  In  the  field  of  drugs  and  cosmetics, 
particularly,  there  are  wide  differences  between  the  prices  of  virtually 
identical  products.  Some  of  these  depend  upon  extensive  advertising 
for  their  popularity,  others  are  pushed  by  dealers  because  they  yield 
high  distributive  margins,  still  others  are  offered  to  the  consumer 
at  low  prices.  These  techniques  may  not  be  of  equal  social  and 
economic  desirability;  yet  from  a  purely  business  point  of  view  each 
has  been  rewarded  with  a  degree  of  success.     If  the  decision  is  to 


5  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

stress  advertising,  other  questions  arise.  Effort  may  be  concentrated 
upon  giving  the  consumer  accurate  information  as  to  the  nature  and 
use  of  the  product,  or  the  appeal  may  be  primarily  emotional,  with 
little  or  no  attempt  to  present  reliable  information.  In  any  event 
price,  as  such,  is  in  part  the  result  of  a  decision  on  advertising  policy. 

These  are  but  a  few  of  the  choices  which  business  men  must  make 
in  planning  their  sales  policies.  As  in  the  case  of  price  policy  narrowly 
understood,  the  degree  of  discretion  varies  but  it  is  never  unlimited. 
The  tactics  of  rival  concerns  and  the  preferences  and  prejudices  of 
consumers  must  always  be  considered.  Such  limits  of  discretion 
establish  the  framework  within  which  business  sales  strategy  must 
be  planned.  The  broad  objectives  of  this  strategy  may  now  be 
considered. 

In  a  competitive  economy,  it  is  axiomatic  that  the  policy  decisions 
of  individual  business  concerns  are  primarily  directed  toward  in- 
creasing profits.  It  is  much  more  difficult  to  generalize  with  respect 
to  the  strategy  selected  to  achieve  this  end.^  Nevertheless,  the 
evidence  seems  to  warrant  several  observations. 

Because  of  the  intimate  relationship  between  prices  and  profits, 
businessmen  are  traditionally  eager  to  increase  the  degree  of  dis- 
cretion which  they  can  exercise  with  regard  to  the  price  structure. 
They  are  understandably  reluctant  to  permit  the  course  of  prices  to 
be  determined  entirely  by  the  impersonal  forces  of  the  market.  Often, 
though  not  necessarily,  this  implies  a  striving  toward  price  stability; 
toward  relatively  infrequent  changes  in  price  as  a  means  of  facilitating 
business  planning. 

The  tactics  by  which  control  over  price  can  be  achieved  are  pro- 
foundly affected  by  the  nature  of  the  commodity  mvolved.  In  the 
case  of  some  products,  such  as  wheat  or  ingot  copper,  buyors  do  not 
generally  recognize  any  difference  between  the  wares  of  rival  sellers. 
These  will  be  referred  to  for  convenience  as  "standard"  commodities. 
The  absence  of  any  form  of  buyer  preference  means  that  no  individual 
seller  can,  for  any  appreciable  period,  charge  a  significantly  higher 
price  for  his  product  than  is  being  quoted  by  his  rivals.  There  may 
be  exceptional  cases  in  which  a  concern  controls  so  large  a  share  of 
the  total  supply  of  the  product  that  buyers  cannot  satisfy  their  re- 
quirements without  patronizing  it;  under  such  circumstances  it  is 
conceivable  that  price  differentials  can  be  maintained.  In  general, 
however,  it  is  clear  that  individual  sellers  of  standardized  products 
cannot  effectively  maintain  independent  price  policies.  The  formula- 
tion of  price  policies  and  the  achievement  of  price  stability  for  goods 
of  this  kind  requires,  in  one  form  or  another,  the  participation  of  all 
or  most  competing  producers. 

However,  for  many,  perhaps  most,  manufactured  goods  a  different 
situation  prevails.  Buyers  of  such  items  as  automobiles,  or  dresses, 
or  aspirin,  for  example,  do  not  generally  consider  the  merchandise 
offered  by  competing  sellers  to  be  equally  desirable  in  all  respects. 
The  difference  between  rival  merchandise  may  relate  to  inherent  physi- 
cal characteristics  involving  such  factors  as  quality,  performance, 
style,  or  taste.     However,  buyer  preference  may  exist  without  such 

'  One  of  the  many  considerations  Involved  may  be  the  relative  emphasis  placed  by  business  coneerrn 
upon  Immediate  profits  from  quick  turnover,  profits  over  the  Intermediate  term,  and  profits  over  a  long 
term  of  years. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  7 

physical  differences;  trade-marks,  brand  names,  or  the  prestige  of  the 
manufacturer  or  distributor  may  be  the  significant  elements.  The 
important  point  is  the  buyer's  psychological  appraisal;  the  heliej  that 
a  difference  exists  which  makes  one  product  more  desirable  than 
another  at  the  same  price,  or  that  the  payment  of  a  premium  for  one 
as  compared  with  another  is  warranted.  Commodities  of  this  kind 
may  be  termed  "differentiated." 

There  is,  of  course,  no  sharp  line  of  demarcation  between  "stand- 
ard" and  "differentiated"  products,  but  rather  an  insensible  gradation. 
The  difference  between  two  makes  of  automobiles  is  probably  more 
apparent  to  the  buyer  than  that  between  two  makes  of  tires,  yet  it  is 
clear  that  in  the  latter  case,  too,  such  differences  are  by  no  means  a 
negligible  factor  in  the  market.  Brand  prestige-  is  more  important 
for  aspirin  than  it  is  for  canned  vegetables  and,  in  turn,  more  for  canned 
vegetables  than  for  sugar;  yet  even  in  the  case  of  sugar,  brands  play  a 
definite  role  in  differentiating  the  product  of  one  seller  from  that  of 
another.  Moreover,  in  the  case  of  products  apparently  "standard," 
such  as  steel  rails,  there  may  be  such  differences  in  promptness  of 
deliveiy  or  perhaps  in  incidental  services  rendered  as  would  result  in 
the  creation  of  buyer  preferences. 

For  the  purpose  of  the  present  discussion,  however,  this  distinction 
between  markets  in  which  buyer  preference  is  imimportant  and  those 
in  which  it  plays  a  significant  role  is  useful;  although  the  lack  of  any 
sharp  dividing  line  should  be  constantly  borne  in  mind.  The  existence 
of  buyer  preferences,  however  achieved,  yields  to  the  individual  seller 
an  important  degree  of  latitude  in  formulating  his  price  policy  without 
constant  reference  to  the  actions  of  his  rivals.  It  is  not  necessary  for 
n  manufacturer  whose  product  has  acquired  outstanding  prestige  to 
follow  all  the  ups  aiul  downs  of  the  general  market  for  similar  commod- 
ities. A  number  of  illustrations  of  this  situation  are  assembled  in 
chapter  III  of  this  report  (pp.  75-90) .  For  example,  the  retail  price  for 
a  nationally  advertised  brand  of  men's  business  shirts  showed  prac- 
tically no  change  between  1929  and  the  present,  while  the  prices  of 
less  known  brands  meeting  similar  specifications  declined  materially. 
In  such  fields  as  packaged  medicines,  v/here  it  is  particularly  difficult 
for  the  average  buyer  intelligently  to  compare  the  merits  of  similar 
products,  wide  differences  in  price  can  be  maintained  for  long  periods 
between  merchandise  which  is  virtually  identical  in  all  but  name. 

Since  product  differentiation  increases  the  area  of  price  discretion, 
it  is  not  surprising  that  business  concerns  should  strive  to  create  or 
accentuate  differences — intrinsic  or  apparent — between  their  products 
and  those  of  their  rivals.  During  recent  years  there  has,  in  fnct, 
been  a  distinct  tendency  for  competitive  strategy  to  emphasize 
elements  other  than  price. 

In  addition  to  the  greater  latitude  in  formulating  price  policy 
which  this  teclmiquc  yields,  it  often  seems  expedient  for  other  reasons 
to  base  sales  appeal  upon  nonprice  factors.  As  a  competitive  w(>apon. 
price  reductions  are  double-edged.  A  company  which  reduces  prices 
in  order  to  obtain  business  must  anticipate  the  likelihood  that  its 
competitors  will  follow  its  lead;  that  any  aiivantage  it  gains  mny  be 
no  more  than  momentary.  Most  price  reductions  can  be  duplicated 
exactly;  if  one  concern  reduces  its  prices  by  five  pcrccnl  and  its  rivwls 
follow  the  same  course  their  relative  position  in  the  market  may  be 


24714y— 41    -No    1- 


g  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

unaltered.  Changes  in  quality  features  are  more  difficult  to  duplicate 
quickly  or  precisely,  and  the  competitive  advantage  they  yield  may 
Avell  be  more  lasting. 

In  addition,  producers  of  rival  commodities  are  far  less  likely  to 
i-esent  improvements  in  quality  than  direct  reductions  in  price.  The 
latter  often  lead  to  price  wars,  the  former  rarely.  During  the  last 
20  or  30  years  there  has  been  intensive  and  very  effective  propaganda 
conducted  by  trade  associations  and  by  some  business  concerns  de- 
signed to  convince  businessmen  generally  that  price  competition  is 
somehow  sordid  and  should  be  eliminated.  There  is  today  a  wide- 
spread belief  in  business  circles  that  cempetitive  effort  should  be  di- 
rected toward  the  nonprice  aspects  of  competition  almost  to  the  exclu- 
sion of  price ;  that  sales  campaigns  should  emphasize  quality,  service,, 
and  performance  and  should  avoid  price  cutting  ^  as  a  competitive 
technique. 

The  accentuation  of  product  differences  cannot  of  itself  shield  any 
concern  completely  from  the  impact  of  price  competition.  The 
degree  of  protection  afforded  is  greater  for  some  products  than  for 
others,  but  it  is  never  absolute.  Moreover,  wherever  buyers  are 
equipped  to  compare  the  merits  of  rival  products  intelligently,  price 
differences  cannot  be  ignored.  This  is  particularly  true  in  industrial 
markets;  institutional  buyers  are  usually  more  skilled  than  domestic 
consumers  in  comparing  merchandise  and  price  retains  major  force 
as  a  sales  weapon.  In  the  case  of  raw  materials  and  semimanufac- 
tured goods  it  is  often  difficult  to  create  any  convincing  appearance 
of  product  differentiation. 

Consequently,  the  effort  of  businessmen  to  cushion  the  force  of 
price  competition  cannot  rest  with  the  attempt  to  shift  emphasis  to 
nonprice  channels.  More  direct  schemes  to  achieve  control  of  price 
behavior  remain  conmion.  It  is  not  within  the  scope  of  the  present 
discussion  to  describe  these  devices  in  detail,  but  a  few  illustrations 
are  pertinent. 

The  extreme  case,  of  course,  is  that  of  the  outright  monopoly  whose 
latitude  in  price  policy  formulation  is  limited  only  by  the  possibility 
that  expenditures  will  be  diverted  to  other  products.  However, 
such  situations  are  extremely  rare  in  the  United  States.  Almost  as 
complete  a  degree  of  control  may  be  achieved  through  such  devices 
as  patent  ])ools  or  rigid  licensing  agreements,  such  as  apparently 
prevail  in  the  glass  container  *  and  plasterboard  industries. 

In  the  absence  of  such  conditions,  concerns  in  various  industries 
have  at  times  resorted  to  collusive  agi-eements  for  maintaining  prices 
or  sharing  markets.  The  technique  known  as  price  leadership  may 
represent  an  effort  to  achieve  similar  results  without  overt  violation 
of  the  antitrust  laws.  This  means  that  some  one  concern  in  an  indus- 
try, usually  outstanding  in  size  or  prestige,  regularly  initiates  all 
changes  in  price  and  that  its  competitors  consistently  follow  its  lead." 
Conventional  arrangements  within  an  industry  such  as  basing  point 

>  The  term  "price  cutting"  is  here  used  in  the  sense  commonly  used  by  businessmen;  i.e.  price  reductions 
for  the  purpose  of  gaining  direct  competitive  advantage.  Price  reductions  reflecting  actual  manufacturing 
economies  are  not  in  equal  d  sfavor. 

«  See  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  Hearings,  Part  2,  pp.  377-834. 

«  It  should  be  pointed  out  that  market  situations  which  have  the  outward  appearance  of  "price  leadership" 
may  also  be  accompanied  by  activities  whose  .«tatus  under  the  antitrust  laws  is  more  (luestionable.  For 
example,  the  followingletter  written  by  H.  A.  Dorenbusch,  general  sales  manager  of  the  Newport  Rolling 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  9 

systems,  by  reducing  the  importance  of  plant  location  as  a  competi- 
tive element,  presumably  facilitate  the  maintenance  of  such  price 
understandings.'  The  same  principle  applies  to  what  are  laiown  as 
base-price  systems,  under  which  the  prices  of  many  different  products 
are  determined  by  the  application  of  a  generally  accepted  schedule  of 
extras  and  deductions  to  a  nominal  base  price.  Both  of  these  practices 
are  observed  in  the  steel  industry.  By  reducing  the  points  at  which 
variation  may  occur,  the  formulation  of  price  policy  is  simplified  and 
the  maintenance  of  price  uniformity  between  rival  producers  facili- 
tated. Other  practices  designed  to  achieve  similar  ends  which  may  be 
used  separately  or  in  conjunction  are  open-price  systems  which  permit 
each  concern  to  know  what  its  competitors  are  charging  and  uniform 
cost-accounting  systems  whereby  all  concerns  base  their  pricing  policies 
upon  identical  or  similar  methods  of  calculation. 

Naturally  all  of  these  devices  work  more  smoothly  where  competing 
sellers  are  few  than  where  they  are  many.^  For  example,  in  an  indus- 
tr}^  consisting  of  only  five  concerns  it  is  usually  simpler  to  obtain 
general  observance  of  the  prices  set  by  the  "leader"  than  if  there  were 
a  hundred  concerns.  Even  a  single  company  of  relatively  small  size 
which  elects  to  cut  prices  rather  than  to  conform  with  the  level  quoted 
by  most  of  its  rivals  may  prove  to  be  a  serious  disrupting  influence. 
Although  there  are  many  ways  in  which  more  or  less  direct  coercion 
can  be  applied  to  prevent  such  defections,  these  are  not  always  satis- 
factory or  free  of  danger.  Consequently  control  is  easier  to  exercise 
in  industries  in  which  technological  requirements  make  huge  amounts 
of  capital  necessary  for  successful  operation.  The  number  of  concerns 
in  such  industries  is  necessarily  limited  and  the  entry  of  new  enter- 
prise difficult.  Price  stability  is  also  promoted  because  established 
concerns  are  less  likely,  to  resort  to  aggressive  price  cutting  as  a  means 
of  expanding  their  share  of  the  market  than  new  companies  which  are 
seeking  to  win  a  place  for  themselves. 

In  summary,  there  is  evidence  that  business  today,  as  in  the  past, 
seeks  to  avoid  the  full  impact  of  price  competition.  Frequent  price 
fluctuations  are  commonly  regarded  as  inexpedient;  some  degree  of 
price  stabihty  is  preferred.  Such  stability  may  be  achieved  by  various 
forms  of  agreement  or  understanding  within  industries  such  as  patent 

Mill  Co  ,  to  the  president  of  that  company,  on  August  17,  1935,  suggests  that  price  leadership  is  occasionally 
implemented  by  more  positive  methods: 

"Mr.  A.  K.  ANDREWS, 

Footes  Bay,  Ontario,  Canada. 

"Dear  Mr.  A.  K.:  It  was  not  definitely  decided  until  late  last  evening  to  put  into  effect  for  fourth  quarter 
a  one-price  policy  allowing  the  galvanized  sheet  price  to  remain  at  $3.10  per  100  pounds  for  No.  24  gauge  base 
f.  o.  b.  Pittsburgh.  A  few  of  the  larger  interests  such  as  Weirton  and  Inland  were  in  favor  of  reducing  the 
price  to  $3  base  for  No.  24  gauge  f.  o.  b.  Pittsburgh  but  this  was  finally  defeated  and.it  was  agreed.to>llow  all 
prices  to  remain  the  same  as  now  in  effect. 

"The  announcement  of  no  further  jobber  allowance  after  October  1  will  be  made  by  Continental  on  Tues- 
day of  next  week  after  which  all  mills  can  announce  likewise.  We,  of  course,  in  the  meantime  will  notify 
our  people  which  no  doubt  will  be  conducive  of  causing  an  influx  of  jobber  business  for  shipmont  prior  to 
October  l. 

"It  is  my  intention  to  discuss  this  with  Mr.  Little  this  morning  so  that  we  will  be  prepared  to  take  care  of  ■ 
the  rush  that  we  like  others  will  no  doubt  have  during  the  month  of  September. 

"I  discussed  the  automotive  situation  with  Noll  Flora,  secretary  of  the  National  Association  of  'Fl-it 
Rolled  Steel  Manufacturers,  last  evening  and  he  informed  me  that  while  some  little  tonnage  wa=  pT'.ced 
several  weeks  ago,  nothing  more  has  been  done  and  that  all  the  mills  are  holding  firmly  to  their  prices  s'ld  are 
expecting  that  additional  tonnages  will  have  to  be  placed  soon."  (Temporf'-y  National  Econoinc  Com- 
mittee, Hearings,  Part  27,  morning  session,  January,.30,  1940.) 

•  See  I  art  II  of  this  volume. 

'  But  the  mere  force  of  business  custom  may  be  responsible  for  generalinaint^^nance  of  pricia  [sracticos  in 
otherwise  highly  competitive  industries,  such  as  the  garment  trades,  whpre  cc.^ip^tition  is  on  sf  yle  and  other 
nonprice  factors. 


IQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOISIIC  POWER 

controls,  collusive  aiTangemcnts  or  perhaps  by  the  price  leadership 
technique.  The  multiplication  and  accentuation  of  differences 
between  rival  products,  by  diverting  competition  from  price  channels, 
has  also  yielded  individual  concerns  greater  latitude  in  determining  the 
prices  of  their  wares. 

These  trends  are  specific  examples  of  the  manner  in  which  sales 
policy  decisions  of  business  concerns  affect  the  structure  of  the  market. 
More  generally,  it  is  clear  that  the  orientation  of  business  policy  has 
important  consequences  for  the  functioning  of  the  economy.  It 
influences  the  pattern  and  behavior  of  prices,  the  amount  and  variety  of 
goods  produced,  the  level  of  employment  and  the  standard  of  living  of 
the  population.  It  is  in  the  light  of  these  effects  upon  the  general 
well-being  that  basic  issues  of  public  concern  arise. 

Two  of  these  basic  issues  have  been  selected  for  analysis  in  this 
report.  The  first  relates  to  the  effects  of  business  price  policy  deci- 
sions, as  reflected  in  the  behavior  of  commodity  prices,  upon  recession 
and  recovery.  The  second  concerns  the  economic  implications  flov/ing 
from  broad  choices  of  competitive  strategy,  particularly  as  expressed 
in  the  trend  toward  nonprice  competition,  upon  the  manner  in  which 
economic  resources  are  used,  and  upon  the  general  standard  of  living. 

These  issues  necessarily  overlap,  since  the  behavior  of  prices  is 
importantly  affected  by  the  direction  which  competition  takes.  Con- 
versely, prices  and  price  movements  in  the  abstract  have  little  signifi- 
cance. It  is  idle  to  inquire  merely  whether  a  particular  price  is  high 
or  low,  whether  it  fluctuates  freely  or  infrequently,  whether  its  long- 
term  trend  is  up  or  down,  or  even  whether  it  reflects  impersonal  market 
forces,  price  policy  decisions,  or  perhaps  monopoly  control.  The 
behavior  of  the  prices  of  any  commodity  is  significant  only  when  it  is 
related  to  its  broad  economic  setting. 

Nevertheless,  it  is  useful  to  examine  these  two  problems  separately, 
though  their  related  character  must  be  borne  in  mind  constantly. 
This  is  done  in  the  two  chapters  immediately  following.  In  the  final 
chapter  the  issues  are  once  more  brought  together;  the  character  and 
implications  of  the  policy  decisions  confronting  the  members  of  a  group 
of  industries  are  examined  in  some  detail. 


CHAPTER  IP 
PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 

SUMMA.RY 

Prices  of  difTcrent  commodities  respond  quite  differently  to  changes 
in  market  conditions.  Tliis  is  particularly  apparent  during  periods  of 
violent  economic  upheaval,  when  the  entire  price  structure  is  being  sub- 
jected to  powerful  unsettling  influences.  During  the  1929-33  depres- 
sion, for  example,  while  the  prices  ^  of  such  commodities  as  copper  or 
hides  showed  extreme  declines  of  over  70  percent,  the  prices  of  other 
items  such  as  agricultural  implements  and  anthracite  coal  scarcely 
fell  at  all.  Prices  in  the  (irst  category  are  called  flexible,  or  sensitive; 
those  in  the  second  rigid,  inflexible,  or  insensitive. 

These  difl'erences  in  price  behavior  have  man}'  causes.  Some  are 
peculiar  to  the  commodities  in  question;  for  example,  the  extreme 
decline  in  the  price  of  rubber  during  the  depression  was  at  least 
partly  due  to  the  devaluation  of  the  pound  sterling,  while  the  increase 
in  the  price  of  hops  between  1929  and  1933  may  bo  traced  to  the 
legnlization  of  beer.  In  addition,  however,  more  general  considera- 
tions, such  as  intrinsic  differences  in  market  structure,  play  an 
im])ortant  role.  It  was  pointed  out  in  the  preceding  chapter  that  the 
prices  of  different  com.moditJes  are  influenced  in  varying  degrees  by 
the  price  policy  decisions  of  business  concerns.  It  is  probably  true 
that  prices  are  most  flexible  v/here  individual  producers  enjoy  little  or 
no  discretion  in  determining  their  price  policies  and  that  outstand- 
ingly rigid  prices  usually  occur  whore  a  high  degree  of  latitude  in 
price  policy  formulation  is  available.  Presumably  this  reflects  the 
general  preference  of  business  concerns  for  relatively  stable  prices 
and  the  fact  that  business  price  policy  is  directed  accordmgly. 
^\^lether  or  not  such  policy  decisions  necessarily  denote  the  presence 
of  "inonopoly"  in  the  sense  implied  in  the  antitrust  laws,  there  is 
little  doubt  that  the  development  of  restrictive  trade  practices  of 
many  kinds  aimed  directly  or  incidentally  at  achieving  price  stabiliza- 
tion have  decreased  the  fluctuations  of  prices  of  certain  commodities. 

These  difl'erences  in  price  behavior  between  different  t3'pes  of 
commodities  are  in  no  sense  new  phenomena.  It  has  long  been  ob- 
served, for  example,  that  the  price  movements  of  manufactured  goods 
are  in  general  narrower  than  those  of  agricultural  products.  Never- 
theless, there  is  evidence  that  the  far-reaching  technological  changes 
of  recent  years  have  materially  altered  the  structure  of  man}'  markets 

'  Ch.  n  was  prepared  by  Raul  Nelson.  Walter  O.  Keim  devised  the  Index  of  price  dispersion  and  con- 
tributed to  tbe  sections  on  Price  Relationships  and  Prices  and  Production.  Joseph  W.  Lethco  assisted  In 
preparinf;  the  statistical  data. 

>  In  this  discussion  the  term  "price",  unless  otherwise  noted,  Is  used  to  signify  wholesale  price  and  par- 
ticularly wholesale  price  as  reported  by  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.  The  Bureau's  wholesale  prices 
are  generally  those  received  by  the  producer  or  manufacturer  of  the  item  in  question;  freixht  to  destination 
may  or  may  not  bo  Included.  Wholesale  price  in  this  sense  docs  not  mean  the  price  paid  by  retailers  to 
wholesalers. 

11 


12  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEll 

and  that,  as  a  result,  inflexible  prices  play  a  somewhat  more  important 
role  in  the  economy  today  than  was  true  a  generation  ago. 

There  has  been  much  controversy  regarding  the  economic  accompa- 
niments of  these  differences  in  price  behavior.  This  controversy  has 
centered  about  the  effects  of  price  rigidity  upon  the  economy  during 
periods  of  general  business  depression;  little  or  no  attention  has  been 
devoted  to  the  problems  arising  during  booms.  It  has  been  contended 
that,  in  general,  the  decline  in  production  and  employment  during 
periods  of  recession  is  considerably  more  marked  in  those  industries 
whose  price  structures  are  rigid  than  in  those  whose  prices  are  flexible. 
Especial  stress  has  been  placed  upon  the  plight  of  the  farmer;  upon  the 
contrast  between  the  sustained  production  and  falling  prices  which 
characterized  the  products  which  he  had  to  sell,  and  the  curtailed 
production  and  sustained  prices  of  those  industrial  products  which  he 
had  to  buy. 

It  has  been  argued  that  the  decline  in  production  and  employment 
in  many  lines  during  the  dowxiturn  of  1929-33  would  have  been  less 
drastic  if  price  readjustments  had  been  greater.  Similarly,  decisions 
by  business  concerns  to  increase  the  prices  of  certain  products  during 
the  winter  of  1936-37  may  have  played  a  role  in  checking  recovery, 
particularly  in  the  construction  industry.  Although  this  is  no  doubt 
true  in  certain  cases,  the  analysis  presented  in  this  chapter  emphasizes 
the  fact  that  the  relationship  existing  between  price  and  production 
for  anv  specific  commodity  is  extremely  complex  and  that  it  is  im- 
possible to  conclude  that  uniform  flexibihty  of  prices  even  if  it  were 
possible  would  turn  the  tide  of  depression  and  bring  about  recovery. 
For  example,  there  is  a  numerous  class  of  products  for  which  isolated 
changes  in  prices  are  unlikely  to  be  reflected  in  material  changes  in 
consumption.  Thus  demand  for  any  building  material  is  determined 
largely  by  the  general  rate  of  building  activity.  A  reduction  in  the 
price  of  building  tile  taken  alone,  for  example,  would  probably  have 
so  small  an  effect  upon  the  total  cost  of  building  that  its  demand  would 
not  be  appreciably  stimulated  thereby.  Similar  instances  of  "joint 
demand"  occur  in  almost  every  field.  The  sale  of  buttons  or  of  yarn 
depends  upon  that  of  apparel;  the  demand  for  spark  plugs  in  part 
upon  that  for  automobiles,  etc.  Isolated  changes  in  the  prices  of  such 
individual  commodities  can  have  little  or  no  effect  upon  the  cost  or 
price  of  the  finished  product  and  consequently  upon  their  own  sales, 
though  in  combination  with  similar  changes  in  the  prices  of  related 
products  their  cumulative  effect  may  be  very  considerable. 

Moreover,  there  are  certain  distinct  limitations  to  the  extent  to 
which  price  reductions  might  be  expected  to  stimulate  the  sales  of 
certain  kinds  of  product  during  periods  of  severely  curtailed  purchasing 

f)ower.  This  is  particularly  true  of  those  products  which  are  not  abso- 
ute  necessities  of  life  or  whose  purchase  can  be  postponed,  such  as 
durable  goods.  For  example,  sales  of  agricultural  machinery  during 
1932  had  declined  to  18  percent  of  their  1929  level.  In  all  probability, 
reduced  prices  would  have  stimulated  sales  somewhat.  However,  the 
decline  in  sales  was  largely  due  to  the  fact  that  the  income  of  most 
farmers  had  fallen  so  low  that  it  was  completely  earmarked  for  ex- 
penditures that  would  brook  no  postponement  such  as  taxes,  interest, 
food,  fuel,  seed,  and  the  like.  There  was  nothing  left  over  for  pur- 
chases which  could  be  delayed  a  year  or  two,  and  machinery  generally 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13 

fell  into  this  latter  class.  It  is  possible  that  prompter  price  readjust- 
ments for  those  products  during  the  initial  phases  of  a  business  decline 
might  retard  the  do^vntu^n,  but  the  effect  of  practicable  price  reduc- 
tions after  the  income  of  the  farmer  has  already  declined  materially 
is  clearly  limited.  Similar  considerations  apply  to  many  other  pro- 
ducts such  as  automobiles,  furniture,  jewelry,  and,  even  in  a  more 
limited  degree,  to  clothing. 

The  structure  of  the  economy  imposes  another  serious  limitation 
upon  the  benefits  which  might  be  derived  from  greater  declines  in 
prices  which  are  more  or  less  inflexible  during  a  depression  period.  It 
has  been  argued  that  the  disturbance  of  market  relationships  would  be 
minimized  if  all  prices  rose  and  fell  freely  in  response  to  changing 
economic  conditions.  It  is  contended,  for  example,  that  if  the  prices 
of  what  the  farmer  had  to  buy  had  fallen  about  as  sharply  as  did  the 
prices  of  the  things  he  had  to  sell,  the  effects  which  flowed  from  the 
contraction  of  his  purchasing  power  could  have  been  largely  avo'ted. 
However,  this  would  have  been  completely  true  only  if  all  prices  had 
been  equally  free  to  move;  that  is,  if  wages,  interest  rates,  utility  rates, 
the  prices  of  services,  rents,  depreciation,  taxes,  and  so  on  had  all 
fallen  together.^  Moreover,  it  assumes  the  absence  of  long-term  loans 
and  mortgages  which  require  fixed  servicing  regardless  of  price  trends. 
In  other  words,  increased  sensitivity  of  commodity  prices  alone  can 
only  have  limited  (though  perhaps  significant)  effect  unless  these  other 
types  of  noncommodity  prices  are  also  flexible. 

All  these  factors  must  be  accorded  due  weight  in  orienting  public 
policy  to  deal  with  the  problem  of  recovery  insofar  as  it  is  related  to 
prices  alone.  Thus  it  remains  to  define  the  objectives  of  public  policy 
in  relation  to  prices.  So  far,  there  has  been  a  notable  lack  of  any 
concrete  suggestions  for  a  cooi'dinated  approach  to  governmental 
action  with  regard  to  price  policies.^  Although  it  is  no  doubt  true 
that  the  extreme  disparities  in  price  behavior  exhibited  since  1929 
materially  aggravated  the  recession  and  retarded  recovery,  there  is 
no  evidence  to  show  that  it  would  be  desirable — even  if  it  were  pos- 
sible— for  all  prices  to  be  equally  sensitive  to  changing  business 
conditions. 

It  may  well  be  that  by  attacking  monopolistic  prices  which  are  in 
any  event  objectionable,  the  flexibility  of  the  prices  of  the  products 
affected  can  be  increased.  But  it  is  particularly  important  that  the 
limited  character  of  the  benefits  which  could  be  derived  from  inducing 
isolated  price  changes  be  recognized. 

It  is  apparent,  therefore,  that  any  appraisal  of  this  issue  of  price 
sensitivity  must  consider  the  economy  as  a  generally  interdependent 
whole.  Although  there  are  certain  broad  sectors  of  the  economy — 
e.  g.,  the  construction  industry — which  may  for  some  purposes  be 
considered  independently  of  other  sectors,  it  must  be  recognized  that 
a  commodity  by  commodity  approach  to  the  problem  is  of  little  value. 
The  effects  of  price  changes  must  be  considered  in  combination  with 
each  other  and  with  the  behavior  of  noncommodity  prices  as  well. 
It  must  also  be  recognized  that  changes  in  price  will  themselves 

•  Of  course  there  is  no  implication  that  these  declines  should  be  proportional. 

«  A  set  of  general  principles  was  prepared  by  an  interdepartmental  committee  and  announced  by  Presi- 
dent Roosevelt  on  February  18,  1939;  these  dealt  with  objectives  rather  than  methods. 


24  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

affect  the  income  of  producers  and  thereby  alter  the  aggregate  na- 
tional purchasing  power — as  well  as  its  distribution. 

Moreover,  it  should  be  emphasized  that  wholesale  commodity  prices 
are  only  one  part  of  the  picture.  Price  movements  on  retail  markets 
are  usually  narrower  than  at  the  wholesale  level.  In  some  fields 
price  rigidities  are  introduced  and  aggravated  by  the  present  system 
of  distributing  goods  from  producer  to  consumer  as  indicated  in 
chapter  III.  Much  recent  legislation — both  State  and  national — 
has  had  as  a  major  or  incidental  objective  the  protection  of  traditional 
channels  of  distribution  against  the  impact  of  newer  methods  of 
selling.  This  is  true,  for  example,  of  chain-store  taxes,  resale  price 
maintenance  laws  (the  so-called  Fair  Trade  Acts),  the  Unfair  Prac- 
tices Acts  ^  and  antidiscrimination  laws  such  as  the  Robin  son-Pa  tman 
Act.  If  the  effects  of  price  rigidities  upon  the  economy  are  harmful, 
it  would  seem  desirable  to  avoid  the  enactment  and  administration 
of  legislation  of  this  Idnd. 

Finally,  it  must  be  observed  that  the  approach  to  the  problem  of 
sustained  employment  and  production  via  the  study  of  the  flexibiUty 
of  prices,  v/hile  it  brings  to  hght  certain  industrial  practices  which  may 
bo  in  need  of  correction,  emphasizes  again  that  each  commodity  must 
be  considered  in  relation  to  its  market.  Although  certain  broad 
standards  of  business  conduct,  such  as  those  prescribed  in  the  anti- 
trust laws,  may  be  generally  required,  and  although  the  enforcement 
of  such  standards  may  materially  affect  the  behavior  of  certain  prices, 
yet  it  is  evident  that  no  one  common  remedy  to  induce  greater  flexi- 
bility of  all  prices — were  that  end  clearly  desirable — can  be  devised. 

The  following  analysis  coucems  that  aspect  of  the  problem  upon 
v.'hich  the  discussions  of  recent  years  have  centered — the  effect  of 
price  rigidity  upon  production  and  employment  during  periods  of 
recession  or  of  low  business  activity.  If  the  rate  of  industrial  activity 
should  advance  rapidly,  it  may  become  necessaiy  to  center  attention 
upon  price  'increases  rather  than  price  decreases.  There  may  be  sub- 
stantial advances,  for  example,  in  certain  flexible  prices  which  have 
been  at  relatively  low  levels,  and  at  the  same  time,  there  may  be  also 
marked  increases  in  prices  of  less  flexible  commodities,  particularly 
those  whose  extreme  rigiditj''  during  the  past  decade  reflected  the 
presence  of  some  degree  of  price  control.  Should  this  happen,  ques- 
tions of  public  policy  might  well  focus  upon  types  of  price  adjustments 
which  are  conducive  to  sustained  recovery  in  business,  rather  than 
upon  those  which  might  be  expected  to  check  a  decline  in  business 
activity.  In  the  case  of  some  products,  moreover,  it  may  become 
necessary  to  consider  prices  and  price  relationships  primarily  in  terms 
of  the  speedy  progress  of  a  defense  program,  regardless  of  their 
broader  impact  upon  the  economy. 

THE  NATURE  OF  THE  PROBLEM 

In  the  preceding  chapter  it  was  pointed  out  that  the  prices  of 
different  commodities  are,  to  varying  degrees,  subject  to  the  influence 
of  policy  decisions  by  businessmen.  For  some  products,  such  as  corn 
or  cotton,  the  number  of  buj'^ers  and  sellers  in  the  market  is  so  great 
that  such  individual  pohcy  decisions  can  exercise  no  more  than  an 
infinitesimal  effect.     For  other  products,  including  most  manufactured 

'  state  laws  prohibiting  sales  by  distributors  at  less  than  Invoice  cost,  plus  certain  specified  mark-ups. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  15 

goods  and  some  raw  materials  (e.  g.,  sulfur),  where  the  number  of 
buyers  and  sellers  is  smaller,  the  influence  of  policy  decisions  may  be 
considerable.  For  convenience  in  reference,  prices  in  the  former  group 
have  often  been  called  market  prices  and  those  in  the  latter  group 
policy  influenced  prices.^  Of  course  policy  influenced  prices  are  not 
immune  to  market  influences;  presumably  the  seller  is  guided  by  his 
appraisal  of  market  conditions  in  fixing  his  quotation.  However, 
the  adjustment  of  prices  to  changing  market  conditions  is  less  direct 
and  less  immediate. 

The  connotation  of  the  term  "policy  influenced"  implies  that  the 
individual  seller  (or  buyer)  has  a  degree  of  leeway  in  foimulating  his 
price  policy;  that  he  can  exercise  some  control  over  his  segment  of  the 
market.  However,  it  is  important  to  recognize  that  such  control  is 
not  necessarily  synonymous  with  monopoly  power  in  the  sense  implied 
in  the  antitrust  laws.  Thus,  it  has  been  pointed  out  (see  ch.  I,  p.  6-8) 
that  the  seUers  of  differentiated  products  bearing  distinguishing  names, 
trade-marks  or  brands  may  frame  their  price  policy  without  the  need 
of  constant  reference  to  the  prices  quoted  by  rivals.  Devices  that 
have  been  recognized  as  collusive  or  monopolistic  may  enlarge  the 
area  of  price  control,  but  they  are  not  essential  to  it. 

It  is  important  to  emphasize  that  "policy  influenced"  is  a  relative 
rather  than  an  absolute  concept.  There  is  no  sharp  division,  no 
•dichotomy,  in  the  universe  of  prices,  but  rather  a  gradation.  In  the 
case  of  most  commodities,  there  is  a  constant  interplay  between  price 
policy  decisions  and  the  influence  of  immediate  market  conditions. 
The  relative  importance  of  these  two  factors  is  constantly  shifting; 
for  example,  prices  which  may  largely  reflect  price  policy  decisions 
during  a  normal  market  may  be  largely  market  determined  either 
during  an  extreme  seUers'  market  when  buyers  are  vigorously  bidding 
against  each  other  for  goods,  or  during  a  buyers'  market  when  dis- 
tress induces  sellers  to  offer  wide  concessions  to  obtain  business. 
Moreover  poHcy  influenced  prices  may  be,  and  frequently  are,  altered 
to  meet  the  needs  of  the  individual  transaction.  Even  ia  the  case  of 
such  commodities  as  steel,  usually  considered  an  extreme  example  of 
price  administration,  indirect  rebates  and  concessions  have  been 
granted  where  the  pressure  from  buyers  has  been  sufficiently  great. 

Despite  these  reservations,  the  distinction  is  not  without  meaning. 
The  prices  of  such  commodities  as  automobiles  or  steel,  on  one  hand, 
and  of  wheat,  on  the  other,  are  determined  by  different  processes. 
And,  although  the  process  of  determination  implies  no  necessary  type 
of  price  behavior,  yet  these  differences  are,  in  turn,  frequently  reflected 
in  the  beha\'ior  of  their  respective  price  quotations.*  In  general,  it 
may  be  said  that  market  prices  are  constantly  adjusting  to  every 
change  in  market  conditions,  with  no  single  buyer  or  seller  able  to 
affect  their  level  appreciably.  In  contrast,  the  day-to-day  course  of 
policy  influenced  prices  displays  no  such  constant  adjustment.  A 
common  iUustration  of  this  latter  kind  of  price  making  is  the  automo- 

'  Policy  influenced  prices,  denoting  those  whose  behavior  is  importantly  influenced  by  business  policy 
decisions,  have  often  ijeen  referred  to  in  the  past  as  "administered"  prices.  However,  Mr.  Gardiner  Means, 
who  seems  to  have  originated  the  latter  term,  uses  it  in  a  connotation  somewhat  different  from  that  here 
Imputed  to  policy  influenced  prices.    According  to  Mr.  Means— 

"A  price  can  be  classed  as  an  administered  price  if  it  has  been  set  and  held  constant  for  a  period  of  time 
covering  successive  transactions." 

Mr.  Means  has  called  attention  to  this  difference  in  usage.  In  view  of  the  confusion  which  may  result 
from  employing  the  same  term  to  denote  two  distinct  concepts,  the  phrase  "policy  influenced"  has  been 
used  in  this  report  in  place  of  "administered." 

'  The  term  "quotation"  Is  used  advisedly,  since  these  often  remain  at  unchanged  levels  even  though 
unreported  concessions  or  rebates  are  modifying  actual  prices. 


IQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

bile  industry  in  which  the  producer  sets  the  wholesale  price  for  eacli 
model  at  the  beginning  of  the  production  year  and  maintains  it  at 
that  level  for  many  months  or  for  the  entire  model  year. 

These  differences  in  price  behavior  are  particularly  noticeable  during 
periods  of  severe  economic  upheaval,  when  the  markets  for  virtually 
all  commodities  are  subject  to  violent  unsettling  influences.  Thus 
during  the  general  downswing  of  1929-33  the  prices  of  some  com- 
modities (e.  g.,  cotton,  oats,  steel  scrap)  fell  more  than  60  percent; 
the  prices  of  others  (e.  g.,  salt,  steel  rails,  cigarettes)  remained  rela- 
tively stable;  some,  such  as  the  price  of  gypsum  plaster,  actually  rose 
to  higher  levels  than  prevailed  at  any  time  between  1926  and  1929. 
During  the  subsequent  recovery  from  1933  to  1937  the  picture  was 
reversed ;  the  rise  of  prices  was  roughly  proportional  to  their  previous 
decline. 

Some  relationsliip,  subject  to  very  numerous  exceptions,  may  be 
traced  between  the  manner  in  wliich  commodity  prices  behaved  and- 
the  process  dominant  in  their  determination.  Although  no  attempt 
was  made  to  classify  products  directly  according  to  the  relative  impact 
of  policy  decisions  upon  their  price  structures,  it  seems  broadly  true 
that  "market"  prices  (as  defined  on  p.  15)  fell  farthest  and  recovered 
most;  in  other  words  they  were  most  flexible  or  sensitive.  Prices  of 
commodities  whose  market  structures  make  probable  some  degree  of 
policy  control  in  general  moved  less  widely;  they  tended  to  be  rigid, 
inflexible,  or  insensitive,  though  in  some  cases  at  least  they  apparently 
showed  less  resistance  to  the  rise  than  to  the  decline. 

This  contrast  in  the  behavior  of  the  wholesale  prices  of  different 
commodities,  reflecting  their  difTerential  responsiveness  to  changing 
market  conditions,  has  received  much  attention  during  recent  years.^ 

*  A  list  of  some  of  the  princijial  recent  works'on  (he  subject  follows. 

BOOKS  AND  DOCUMENTS 

!Nrenn'5,  Gnrdiner  C,  Industrial  Prices  and  Their  Relative  Inflexibility  (74th  Cong.,  1st  scss.,  Doc.  No. 
13,  1935). 

Mills,  Frederick  C,  Prices  in  Recession  and  Recovery,  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research,  1936. 

Burns,  Arthur  R.,  The  Decline  of  Competition,  McGraw-Uill,  1936. 

Tintiier,  Gerhard,  Prices  in  the  Trade  Cycle  (in  United  States  of  America  obtainable  from  G.  E.  Stechert 
&  Co.,  New  York  City),  1935. 

Kreps,  Theodore  J.,  Economic  Problems  in  a  Changing  World,  a  symposium,  chs.  VIII-XV,  Farrar  and 
Rhiuehart,  1939. 

The  Structure  of  the  American  Economy,  National  Resources  Committee,  June  1939. 

ARTICLES 

Mason,  Edward  S.,  Price  Inflexibility,  Review  of  Economic  Statistics,  May  1938. 

Means,  Gardiner  C,  Notes  on  Inflexible  Prices,  American  Economic  Review,  Supplement  XXVI,  No.  1, 
March  1930. 

Tucker,  Riifus,  The  Nature  and  Afeaning  of  Rigid  Prices,  The  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  October 
1937;  The  Reasons  for  Price  Rigidity,  American  Economic  Review,  March  1938. 

Humphrey,  Don  D.,  The  Nature  and  Meaning  of  Rigid  Prices,  The  Journal  of  Political  Economy, 
October  1937. 

Oalbraith,  J.  K.,  Monopoly  Power  and  Price  Rigidities,  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  IN^ay  1936. 

Douglas,  Paul  H.,  What  Shall  We  Do  About  Monopoly  Prices?,  Journal  of  the  Society  for  the  Advance- 
ment of  Management,  March  1937. 

Wood,  Ralph  C,  Dr.  Tucker's  "Reasons"  for  Price  Rigidity,  American  Economic  Review,  December 
1938. 

Stevens,  W.  H,  S.,  Has  Competition  Declined?,  Journal  of  Marketing,  .Vpril  1939. 

J^ederer,  Einil,  Price  Dislocations  versus  Investments,  Social  Research,  May  1938. 

Wallace,  Donald  H.,  Monopoly  Prices  and  Depression,  Explorations  in  Economics,  Notes  and  Essays 
Contributed  in  Honor  of  F.  W.  Taussig,  p.  349,  1936. 

Singer,  H.  W.,  The  Inflexibility  of  the  Price  System,  paper  before  the  Manchester  Statistical  Society, 
January  11,  1939. 

Bachman,  Jules,  Price  Flexibilify  and  Changes  in  Production,  National  Industrial  Conference  Board 
Bulletin,  February  20,  1939. 

PAPERS 

Proceedings  of  the  Academy  of  Political  Sc«ience,  January  1939,  Monopoly  and  Competition  in  Industry 
and  Labor. 

American  Economic  Association,  American  Statistical  Association,  and  American  Association  tor  Labor 
Legislation,  Papers  on  Price  Policy,  December  1938. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  17 

The  sharp  decline  experienced  by  the  prices  of  certain  commodities 
during  depression  has  been  contrasted  with  the  apparent  stabihty  or 
rigidity  of  others.  It  has  been  suggested  repeatedly  that  the  presence 
of  Wese  rigid  prices  has  interfered  materially  with  the  process  by 
which  each  economic  maladjustment  might  otherwise  automatically 
induce  its  own  swift  cure.  The  persistent  underutilization  of  our 
economic  resources  since  1929  has  been  accordingly  attributed,  at 
least  in  part,  to  the  prevalence  of  these  rigidities,®  or  to  the  failure  of 
Government  policy  to  take  account  of  their  existence. 

In  brief,  these  arguments  may  be  summarized  as  follows: 

(1)  The  prices  of  the  commodities  on  our  markets  may  be  divided 
into  two  fairly  distinct  categories,  depending  upon  the  process  domi- 
nant in  their  determination.  Where  immediate  market  forces  are 
uppermost,  prices  tend  to  be  flexible,  or  highly  responsive  to  changing 
economic  conditions.  Where  businessmen  have  a  degree  of  freedom 
in  determining  price  policy,  prices  are  usually  more  rigid  or  less  sensi- 
tive to  immediate  market  forces.'" 

(2)  These  discrepancies  in  price  behavior,  while  not  precisely  new 
phenomena,  have  for  a  variety  of  reasons  been  accentuated  during 
recent  years. 

(3)  Certain  consequences  have  ensued  from  this  development, 
including  particularly: 

(a)  The  "automatic  forces"  which  classical  economists  presumed 
would  regulate  the  economy  have  been  impair.ed  "because  the  con- 
ditions which  once  promoted  the  easy  and  equitable  operation  of  such 
forces  have  ceased  to  exist."  "  The  failure  of  "natural"  recovery  to  set 
in  during  the  depression  has  been  attributed  at  least  partly  thereto. 

It  has  been  contended  that  where  prices  are  inflexible  the  burden 
of  adjusting  to  changing  conditions  necessarily  falls  upon  production 
rather  than  upon  prices  and  that,  as  a  result,  manufacturing  activity 
and  employment  are  curtailed  far  more  sharply  during  periods  of 

'  Thus  to  Prof.  Henry  C.  Simons,  "The  existence  of  extreme  inflexibility  in  large  areas  of  the  price  struc- 
ture was  one  of  the  primary  factors  in  the  phenomenon  of  severe  depression.  This  inflexibility  increases 
the  economic  loss  and  human  misery  accompanying  a  given  deflation  and  causes  deflation  itself  to  proceed 
much  further  than  it  otherwise  would."  (Prof.  Henry  C.  Simons,  A  Positive  Program  for  Laissez  Faire, 
University  of  Chicago  Press,  p.  14.) 

'0  Thus,  according  to  Gardiner  C.  Means,  "•  *  •  the  widespread  presence  in  our  economy  of  inflexible 
administered  prices"  *  •  •  had  "produced  highly  disrupting  effects  in  the  functioning  of  the  economy" 
•  •  •  and  was  •  •  *  "largely  responsible  for  the  failure  of  a  policy  of  laissez  faire  •  •  *  there 
are  two  essentially  difTerent  types  of  market  in  operation — the  traditional  market  in  which  supply  and 
demand  are  equated  by  a  flexible  price  and  the  administered  market  in  which  production  and  demand  are 
equated  at  an  inflexible  administered  price.  In  the  first  type  of  market  economic  adjustments  are  brought 
about  primarily  by  fluctuations  in  price.  In  the  second  type  of  market  economic  adjustments  arc  brought 
about  primarily  by  changes  in  volume  of  production,  while  price  changes  are  of  secondary  significance  in 
producing  adjustment. 

"The  difference  between  market  prices  and  ndministered  prices  is  clear.  A  market  price  is  one  which 
is  made  in  the  market  as  the  result  of  the  interaction  of  buyers  and  sellers.  The  prices  of  wheat  and  cotton 
are  market  prices  as  are  many  other  agricultural  products.  This  is  the  type  of  price  around  which  tradi- 
tional economic  theory  has  been  built. 

"An  administered  price  is  essentially  difTerent.  It  is  a  price  which  is  set  by  administrative  action  and 
held  constant  for  a  period  of  time.  We  have  an  admini'^tered  price  when  a  company  maintains  a  posted 
price  at  which  it  will  make  sales  or  simply  has  its  own  prices  at  which  buyers  may  purchase  or  not  as  they 
wish.  Thus,  when  the  General  Motors  management  sets  its  wholesale  price  for  a  particular  model  and  holds 
that  price  for  6  months  or  a  year  the  price  is  an  administered  price.  Many  wholesale  and  most  retail  prices 
are  administered  rather  than  market  prices.  For  administered  prices  the  price  is  rigid,  at  least  for  a  period 
of  time,  and  sales  (and  usually  production)  fluctuate  with  the  demand  at  tlio  rigid  price."  (Mean--.  Gardi- 
ner C,  Industrial  Prices  and  Their  Relative  Inflexibility  (74th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  S.  Doc.  No.  13).) 

"  Thus,  according  to  an  extensive  analysis  of  the  Canadian  economy,  conducted  during  19.34  and  lOS.'i  by 
a  Royal  Commission,  "It  is,  furthermore,  a  tracjie  delusion  that  the  solution  for  these  economic  problems 
can  be  left  to  automatic  forces,  because  i  he  conditions  wtiich  once  permit  led  the  easy  and  equitable  operation 
of  such  forces  have  ceased  to  exist.  These  conditions  presupposed  two  things,  first,  an  economic  system 
composed  of  small  Independent  units,  no  one  of  which  counted  in  that  system  for  more  than  an  element  in 
a  statistical  average;  second,  the  free  appearance  and  disappearance  of  these  units  and  their  free  entry  into 
and  withdrawal  from  the  market.  With  the  growth  of  imperfect  competition,  however,  these  conditions 
no  longer  exist.  Nor  can  we  assume  any  longer  that  this  monopolistic  tendency  is  a  merely  incidental  in- 
trusion into  a  system  predominantly  and  naturally  competitive."  (Report  of  the  Royal  Commission  on 
Price  Spreads,  ch.  II,  p.  B.) 


Ig  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

recession  than  would  be  true  if  prices  fell  more  rapidly.  "Necessary 
(price)  readjustments  are  therefore  concentrated,  on  the  flexible  sec- 
tions of  our  economy  where  their  effect  is  intensified  by  rigidity  in 
other  sections."'^ 

(6)  At  the  same  time  the  discrepant  behavior  of  different  kinds  of 
prices  during  periods  of  recession  is  alleged  to  create  serious  price  un- 
balances between  various  sections  of  the  economy,  destroying  normal 
exchange  relationships,  and  thereby  causing  distress  both  among  buy- 
ers whose  purchasing  power  is  impaired  tind  among  sellers  whoso 
markets  are  narrowed. 

(4)  Public  policy  must  take  cognizance  of  these  effects  of  price  in- 
sensitivity  and  must  in  one  or  another  manner  strive  either  to  reduce 
their  incidence  or  else  to  compensate  for  their  consequences.  Such 
action  forms  a  necessary  part  of  any  program  designed  to  achieve  and 
maintain  a  high  level  of  productive  activity. 

These  contentions  and  inferences  have  been  vigorously  debated. 
Most  of  the  attacks  upon  their  validity  seem  to  have  centered  upon 
questioning  what  seems  largely  a  side  issue;  namely,  that  the  existence 
of  Inflexible  prices  is  largely  a  new  phenomenon.  It  is  argued  that 
these  conditions  have  always  existed,  that  they  are  an  essential  part 
of  the  structure  of  our  economy  and  that  the  basic  causes  underlying 
the  unsatisfactory  character  of  current  adjustments  must  be  sought 
elsewhere. ^^ 

13 1.«  •  •  all  these  circumstances  unbalance  modern  economicsociety  in  thesense  thatnotallofitsparts 
adjust  themeelves  at  the  same  speed  or  in  the  same  degree  to  any  influence  that  makes  itself  felt  at  any  one 
point.  Necessary  readjustments  are  therefore  concentrated  on  the  flexible  sections  of  our  economy,  where 
their  effect  is  intensified  by  the  rigidity  in  other  sections.  When  different  parts  of  a  glass  tumbler  oipand 
or  contract  at  different  rates,  the  whole  glass  may  bo  cracked.  If  the  economic  structure  is  in  part  flexible, 
and  in  part  rigid,  any  strain  may  lead  to  complete  collapse."    (Ibid.) 

•  ••••«• 

And,  according  to  a  subsequent  publication  of  which  Dr.  Means  was  coauthor,  "Wherever  the  new  typo 
of  industrial  unit  has  introduced  the  factor  of  administration,  it  has  substituted  human  judgment  for  auto- 
matic processes.  Where  administration  has  a  hand  in  determining  price  it  undermines  ihe  central  mech- 
anism of  automatic,  flexible  prices  upon  which  the  old  economy  relied  for  its  adjustments.  Where  it  affects 
the  character  of  competition,  it  modifies  the  structural  framework  within  which  economic  activity  is  carried 
on.    Whereitaffectsthenaturcorresultsof  profit  seeking  it  perverts  the  old  economy's  central  drive  *   •   *. 

"The  disastrous  effect  of  this  type  of  price  upon  the  automatic  mechanism  of  the  old  economy  cannot  be 
overstated.  According  to  laissez  faire  assumptions,  there  can  be  no  general  oversupply  of  goods  or  unem- 
ployment of  people  because  prices  will  adjust  until  everything  which  anyone  is  willing  to  sell  is  sold  and 
until  everyone  willing  to  work  is  employed.  But  when  adjustments  are  made  through  volume  of  production 
instead  of  through  price  the  result  is  very  different.  When  a  drop  in  demand  is  met  by  cutting  down  pro- 
duction, workers  are  laid  off.  If  this  is  the  general  reaction  throughout  industry,  there  is  no  place  for  these 
workers  to  go  for  new  jobs  even  if  they  are  willing  to  take  lower  wages,  since  wages  like  other  forms  of  prices 
are  commonly  administered,  particularly  in  the  concentrated  industries.  Without  jobs,  they  cannot  buy, 
and  their  unemployment  leads  to  a  further  drop  in  demand  for  products.  If  adjustment  is  aealn  made  by 
dropping  production  instead  of  by  lowering  price,  the  effect  is  only  to  make  matters  worse  by  laying  off 
more  people  and  thereby  reducing  demand  still  further.  Such  a  process  can  go  on  until  industry  is  virtually 
at  a  standstill  and  unemployment  is  widespread.  In  place  of  the  reactions  that  were  automatically  set  in 
motion  to  restore  a  balance  under  the  old  conditions  of  flexible  prices,  the  opposite  reactions  here  tend  to 
make  the  situation  progressively  more  grave."  (The  Modern  Economy  n  Action,  by  Caroline  F.  Ware 
and  Oardiner  C.  Means,  ch.  II,  pp.  18,  22-23.) 

'3  Thus,  Don  D.  Humphrey  reaches  the  conclusion  that  rigid  prices  are  not  a  unique  characteristic  of 
current  conditions  but  that  they  were  present  also  during  the  entire  period  between  1890  and  today.  (The 
Nature  and  Meaning  of  Rigid  Prices,  1890-1933,  by  Don  D.  Humphrey,  The  Journal  of  Political  Economy, 
vol.  XLV,  No.  5,  October  1937.) 

Similarly,  Rufus  S.  Tucker  in  a  recent  article  wrote:  "It  is  obvious  that  the  two  kinds  of  prices  have 
been  sharply  differentiated  for  at  least  a  century.  In  fact,  that  differentiation  was  commented  on  by 
Adam  Smith  in  1776  when  he  wrote  'that  the  price  of  linen  and  woolen  cloth  is  liable  neither  to  such  fre- 
quent nor  to  such  great  variations  as  the  price  of  corn,  every  man's  experience  will. inform  him.'  And  the 
extent  of  that  differentiation  was  apparently  greater  in  188t  and  1879  than  in  1933.  In  fact,  the  published 
prices  do  not  show  the  whole  of  it,  for  it  is  a  well-known  fact  that  since  1929  some  of  the  'administered' 
products  have  improved  in  quality  and  size  to  such  an  extent  that  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  price 
quotation  is  misleading.  Their  price  has  in  effect  gone  down  more  than  the  quotation  would  indicate." 
(The  Essential  Historical  Facts  About  tJensitive  and  Administered  Prices,  by  Rufus  S.  Tucker,  The 
Annalist,  February  4,  1938,  pp.  195-196.) 

This  last  point  is  criticised  by  Gardiner  O.  Means  on  the  ground  that  it  does  not  take  into  consideration 
the  offsetting  factor  of  improvement  in  the  techniques  of  production  which  tend  to  save  both  macerials 
and  labor:  "Surely  the  engineering  force  which  has  improved  goods  so  greatly  has  not  failed  to  bring  about 
improvements  in  technique  in  productjon  so  as  to  sive  both  materials  and  labor.  When  improvements 
in  technique  of  production  are  offset  against  improvements  in  cost  of  production,  is  it  any  reason  to  think 
that  the  price  figures  published  by  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  would  be  altered  in  a  significant  manner 
by  adjustment  for  both  factors?  This  is  a  matter  which  certainly  should  be  investigated,  but  I  doubt  if 
the  ret  effect  of  a  full  adjustment  would  significantly  alter  the  relational  picture  I  have  presented." 
(Gardiner  C.  Means,  Notes  on  Inflexible  Prices,  The  American  Economic  Review,  Supplement,  March 
1936,> 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  TOWER  19 

That  there  is  some  force  in  these  contentions  is  undeniable.  Never- 
theless, it  does  seem  probable  that  the  relative  importance  of  insensi- 
tive prices  in  our  econom}^  has  increased  materially  during  the  past 
half  century.  In  the  first  place,  the  character  of  the  commodities 
on  our  markets  has  been  undergoing  a  constant  change.  An  ever 
larger  share  of  the  national  income  goes  for  the  purchase  of  manu- 
factured products. ^^  Moreover,  the  degree  of  processing  to  which 
goods  are  subjected  seems  to  be  continually  increasing.  Automobiles 
replace  buggies;  packaged  and  processed  foods  arc  substituted  for 
the  more  staple  items  purchased  by  the  housewife  of  an  earlier  day; 
clothing  is  bought  ready-made  instead  of  being  fabricated  at  homo 
from  piece  goods  or  yarn,  and  so  on  ad  infinitum.  Since  it  is  generally 
conceded  that  the  price  of  manufactured  goods  shows  typically  less 
flexibility  than  that  of  raw  materials  it  may  well  be  inferred  that 
the  area  of  inflexibility  is  increasing. 

At  the  same  time,  the  intensity  of  price  competition  in  many  lines 
has  been  reduced  through  the  operation  of  forces  described  in  the  pre- 
ceding chapter.  Increasing  differentiation  between  the  products  of 
rival  concerns,  changing  business  mores,  and  high  capital  require- 
ments for  entry  into  business  have  all  played  a  role  in  shiftmg  com- 
petitive emphasis  to  nonprice  channels.  Although  statistical  evi- 
dence is  difficult  to  assemble,  it  seems  probable  that  this  changing 
pattern  of  business  relations  has  reduced  the  apparent  flexibility  of 
the  prices  of  a  great  number  of  commodities. 

It  may  be  concluded,  therefore,  that  a  materiall}^  larger  sector  of 
the  price  universe  must  be  classed  as  insensitive  today  than  was  true 
in  the  earlier  years  of  the  twentieth  century.  Consequently,  the 
undoubted  fact  that  certain  prices  have  always  been  less  flexible  than 
others  does  not  negate  the  possibilit,y  that  recent  economic  trends 
have  aggravated  the  disparity.  Nor  is  it  necessarily  pertinent  that, 
as  Tucker  points  out,^^  the  degree  of  divergence  in  behavior  between 
those  prices  which  were  then  flexible  and  those  which  were  then 
inflexible  was  as  great  formerly  as  today.  The  widening  area  of  price 
inflexibility  may  have  transmuted  what  was  once  an  incidental 
phenomenon  into  a  more  serious  unsettling  influence.  Moreover,  it 
is  possible  that  changes  in  surrounding  economic  circumstances  have 
intensified  the  impact  of  types  of  price  behavior  whose  influence  was 
hitherto  obscured.  The  relevancy  of  historical  comparisons  is  clearly 
limited.  Under  the  circumstances,  the  contention  that  price  inflexi- 
bility has  long  existed  does  not  eliminate  the  desirabilit}'-  of  reapprais- 
ing its  efl'ects  in  tlie  light  of  current  conditions. 

The  disagreement  as  to  assumptions  is  reflected  in  the  discussion 
of  programs  for  action.  Those  who  dismiss  the  entire  subject  as 
unimportant  suggest  that  the  efforts  of  government  can  more  profit- 
ably be  expended  in  other  directions.  Unanimity  is  lacking  even 
among  those  who  feel  it  essential  that  steps  be  taken  to  deal  with  the 
problem  presented  by  inflexible  prices.     Some  contend  that  inflexible 

'*  Thus  Ralph  C.  Wood  writes,  "Neither  Gardiner  C.  Means  nor  Dr.  Tucker  •  •  •  has  mentioned 
that  the  relative  importance  of  many  flexible  priced  products,  notably  agricultural  products,  have  greatly 
declined.  The  decline  is  apparent  in  all  the  series  which  may  he  deemed  most  relevant,  physical  volume 
of  output,  value  of  oul  put,  and  number  of  employees.  Conversely,  the  relative  impoi  tance  of  many  inflexi- 
ble priced  products  has  preatly  increased.  •  •  •  Common  ubservntion  powerfully  suggests  that  the 
expanding  area  and  changing  components  of  the  industrial  scene  lia  ve  magnified  the  in.portance  of  inflexible 
prices  and  hence  have  increased  the  rigidity  of  the  prices  in  some  very  fundamental  ways."  (Ralph  O. 
Wood,  Dr.  Tucker's  Reasons  for  I'rice  Rigidity,  American  Economic  Review,  December  1938.) 

'•  Tucker,  op.  cit. 


20  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

prices  should  be  made  more  flexible  so  as  to  allow  a  laissez  faire  policy 
to  work;^^  others  accept  price  inflexibility  as  largely  inevitable  and 
suggest  that  instead  the  fluctuations  of  flexible  prices  be  somehow 
minimized,  or  that  other  techniques  for  insuring  recovery  and  main- 
taining full  employment  be  devised/^  including  perhaps  monetary 
controls. 

Nor  does  any  clear-cut  solution  seem,  as  yet,  to  be  available.  It  is 
the  purpose  of  the  present  chapter  to  present  a  brief  survey  of  some 
of  the  aspects  of  this  issue  of  price  flexibility.  It  is  designed  as  a 
preliminary  exploration  of  the  field  rather  than  as  a  thorough  analysis 
of  the  problem;  it  marshals  the  salient  facts  and  suggests  some  of  the 
attendant  questions  of  public  policy. 

THE    MEANING    OF    FLEXIBILITY 

Any  appraisal  of  the  significance  of  price  flexibility  to  the  functioning 
of  the  economy  must  necessarily  proceed  from  a  definition  of  just 
what  is  meant  by  flexibility.  The  problem  of  definition  may  be 
approached  in  two  ways;  either  by  examining  the  external  character- 
istics of  price  behavior  only,  or  by  considering  such  behavior  in  its 
relation  to  the  nature  of  the  economic  forces  to  which  prices  may  be 
expected  to  respond.  Up  to  a  certain  point  both  approaches  will 
lead  to  a  similar  separation  of  issues. 

An  examination  of  the  behavior  of  many  price  series  over  a  period 
of  time  may  disclose  four  difl'erent  kinds  of  movement: 

(1)  Casual  variation. — An  irregular,  nonpersistent  short  time  varia- 
tion, following  no  clearly  recurrent  pattern,  and  unrelated  to  the 
movement  of  the  general  price  index.  For  purposes  of  reference,  this 
will  be  called  casual  variation. 

(2)  Seasonal  variation. — A  regularly  recurrent  ))attern  of  variation 
with  an  annual  periodicity.  For  example,  successive  years  may  show 
a  fairly  predictable  fall  in  the  price  during  the  snring  and  summer, 
followed  by  a  rise  of  similar  proportions  during  the  fall  and  winter. 
Such  variation  may  be  termed  seasonal. 

(3)  Cyclical  variation. — The  Dohavior  of  the  specific  series  in 
question  will  usually  reflect,  to  a  greater  or  less  extent,  the  broad 
swings  of  the  general  price  index.  Thus  most  prices  participated  in 
the  general  price  decline  between  1929  and  1933,  and  in  the  general 
price  upswing  between  1933  and  1937.  Such  swings  may  be  con- 
veniently called  cyclical.'* 

(4)  Secular  variation. — The  series  may  have  a  specific,  persistent 
long-term  trend  of  its  own,  independent  of  the  movement  of  the  gen- 
eral price  level,  and  extending  over  a  considerable  period  of  time. 
Such  a  trend  is  commonly  termed  "secular." 

i«  This  viewpoint  Is  advanced  by  Robbins,  "In  order  that  recove  -y  may  be  assured  and  future  dislocation 
minimize'l.  it  is  necessary  not  only  that  flexibility  should  be  restored  to  the  prices  of  different  kinds  of  labor 
but  that  flexibility  should  also  be  restored  in  other  markets."  (The  Great  Depression,  MacMillan,  1935, 
p.  189.) 

"  This  appears  to  be  the  opinion  of  Means,  "Finally,  I  want  to  make  it  clear  that  in  pointing  both  to  the 
fact  and  the  importance  of  inflexible  administered  prices  I  am  not  saying  that  the  inflexible  administered 
prices  are  wrong.  They  seem  to  me  inherent  in  modern  technology.  Nor  am  I  saying  that  inflexible  prices 
should  have  come  down  during  the  depression.  According  to  the  rules  of  the  laissez  faire  game,  they  could 
not  be  expected  to  come  dowtu'      (Notes  on  Inflexible  Prices,  loc.  cit.) 

!•  This  terminology  does  net  necessarily  imply  any  postulates  regarding  the  nature  of  the  business  cycle. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  21 

Those  kinds  of  price  variation  may  be  considered  manifestations  of 
similarly  distinguishable  economic  forces.  Thus  casual  variations  re- 
fleojt  shoi't-term  changes  in  market  conditions.  Seasonal  price  move- 
ments grow  out  of  concurrent  regular  fluctuations  in  demand  or  supply. 
The  cyclical  swings  of  a  price  series  are  the  more  or  less  direct  conse- 
quences of,  or  accompaniments  to,  broad  changes  in  the  rate  of  general 
business  activity.  Secular  trends  are  the  expression  of  basic  long-term 
modifications  of  such  factors  as  production  costs,  consmner  require- 
ments, or  market  structures. 

Where  business  policy  decisions  are  a  factor,  the  nature  of  the  varia- 
tion will  be  affected  by  the  goals  of  business  strategy.  For  example, 
piices  may  be  varied  over  the  short-term  in  order  to  obtain  some  imme- 
diate competitive  advantage.  Regular  seasonal  changes  may  be  intro- 
duced for  the  purpose  of  maintaining  uniformity  of  production  sched- 
ules or  shifting  the  burden  of  carrying  inventory.  The  extent  of 
cyclical  variation — or  its  avoidance — may  be  governed  largely  by  the 
effort  t©  minimize  losses  duiing  periods  of  severely  curtailed  demand. 
Over  the  long-term,  price  policies  and  the  response  of  prices  to  changes 
in  costs  and  markets  may  be  governed  by -such  factors  as  the  relative 
emphasis  upon  large  volume  or  unit  profits,  as  well  as  by  the  rate  at 
which  it  is  considered  expedient  to  replace  old  machinery  and  obso- 
lescent methods  by  newer  or  more  efficient  equipment  and  techniques. 

These  four  aspects  of  price  behavior  necessarily  overlap,  as  do  the 
forces  to  which  they  represent  responsiveness.  Nevertheless,  it  is  pos- 
sible to  consider  separately  the  economic  consequences  and  problems 
of  public  policy  flowing  from  each  of  them. 

The  precise  role  of  casual  price  variation— responsiveness  to  forces 
which  persist  for  not  more  than  a  few  months  at  a  time — is  difficult 
to  appraise.  In  some  cases  short-term  price  changes,  particularly  if 
they  are  considerable7in  extent,  may  have  important  consequences 
upon  the  amount  and  direction  of  spending  and  upon  the  use  of  pro- 
ductive resources.  Thus  sharp  price  increases,  even  though  very  tem- 
porary in  character,  which  occur  during  the  initial  stages  of  recovery 
from  depressed  conditions  may  have  very  serious  repercussions;  this 
may  have  been  true,  for  example,  of  the  short-lived  price  increases 
during  the  late  spring  and  early  summer  of  1933.  Promptness  of 
response  to  important  changes  in  conditions  may  be  important;  thus 
immediate  price  reductions  during  the  initial  stages  of  recession  may 
ward  off  the  need  for  later  and  more  drastic  adjustments.  In  many 
cases,  however,  whether  or  not  the  price  of  a  commodity  remains  at 
a  stable  level  for  a  day,  or  a  week,  or  even  a  month,  or  whether  it 
fluctuates  to  a  limited  extent  about  such  a  level  during  this  period, 
seems  of  minor  consequence  in  its  effects  upon  the  orderly  functioning 
of  the  economy. 

In  all  probability,  seasonal  price  variability  is  not  a  fundamental 
issue.  Whether  the  course  of  any  specific  price  is  or  is  not  subject  to 
regukrly  recurring,  predictable  seasonal  fluctuations  is  likely  to  have 
little  ultimate  effect  either  upon  the  total  income  of  the  producers  of 
the  commodity  or  upon  the  total  amount  which  consumers  must  pay 
for  it.    In  other  words,  seasonal  price  behavior  can  play  no  more  than 


22  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

a  limited  role  in  determining  the  distribution  of  purchasing  power  and 
of  productive  resources  between  various  alternative  uses.^® 

The  significance  of  responsiveness  of  commodity  prices  to  long- 
term  or  secular  trends  next  arises.  To  what  extent  do  the  prices  of 
different  commodities  reflect,  over  a  period  of  years,  changes  in  the 
costs  of  production  due  to  technological  improvements,  to  alterations 
in  the  character  or  availability  of  raw  materials,  to  modifications  in 
the  nature  of  the  labor  supply,  and  so  on?  To  what  extent  is  the  price 
of  a  commodity  responsive  to  fundamental  changes  affecting  its  de- 
mand, as  for  example,  changes  in  consuming  habits  or  in  standards  of 
living,  or  possibly  in  the  technical  uses  to  which  it  may  be  put? 
These  are  questions  of  fundamental  importance  to  the  functioning  of 
an  efficient  economic  s,ystem.  Price  trends  over  the  long  term  are 
the  factors  which  ultimately  determine  the  allocation  of  the  nation's 
resources  of  men  and  materials  to  different  uses,  and  the  general  stand- 
ard of  living  and  well-being  of  the  community .^°  However,  "sensi- 
tivity" or  "flexibility"  has  usually  been  discussed  in  relation  to  short 
run  and  cyclical  influences;  consequently  this  question  of  responsive- 
ness of  commodity  prices  to  long-term  influences,  despite  its  impor- 
tance from  the  point  of  view  of  public  policy,  will  not  be  considered 
at  this  point  in  the  analysis. 

Finally,  there  is  the  problem  central  to  the  present  discussion ;  that 
is  the  degree  to  which  specific  commodity  prices  reflect  the  broad  up- 
swings and  downswings  of  wholesale  commodity  prices  in  general. 
The  problem  may  be  formulated  alterDatively  as  one  of  price  respon- 
siveness to  what  are  usually  termed  cyclical  influences,  that  is,  to 
major  changes  in  the  rate  of  business  activity.  It  is  this  aspect  of 
price  sensitivity,  particularly  in  relation  to  periods  of  downtiu-n,  which 
has  been  the  focus  of  most  discussion  ai]d  analysis  in  recent  years.  It 
should  be  noted  that  economists  have  generally  accorded  emphasis  to 
the  behavior  of  prices  during  the  great  depression  of  the  years  1929 
to  1933  and  also  to  their  action  during  the  recession  of  1937  and  1938 
and  have  given  less  attention  to  the  behavior  of  prices  in  periods  of 

"  Qenerally  speaking,  those  prices  which  show  a  regular  pattern  of  seasonal  variation  are  affected  by  one 
of  two  sets  of  influences.  The  first  of  those  reflects  natural  forces  over  which  man  has  little  or  no  control, 
for  example,  seasonal  changes  in  the  production  of  such  commodities  as  milk,  or  butter,  or  fresh  vegetables. 
The  prices  of  most  of  these  products  are  liigher  in  the  winter  than  in  the  summer  because  of  inevitable  differ- 
ences in  cost,  such  as  storage  charges  or  extra  transportation  expenses.  In  such  cases,  therefore,  price  varia- 
tion merely  reflects  seasonal  variation  in  supply  and  in  costs. 

Another  type  of  seasonal  price  variation  results  from  the  more  or  less  deliberate  policy  of  industry— 
frequently  representing  the  crystallization  of  custom — designed  to  even  fluctuations  in  demand,  and  perhaps 
to  permit  the  industry  to  operate  more  efl3ciently.  This  is  true,  for  example,  in  the  case  of  anthracite  coal, 
where  rates  are  systematically  lowered  during  the  summer  in  order  to  stimulate  purchases  during  what 
would  otherwise  be  a  slack  period.  This  custom  is  designed  to  reduce  the  burden  of  seasonal  inventory 
which  the  industry  would  otherwise  have  to  carry.  It  seems  quite  probable  that  this  kind  of  policy  is  reason- 
ably calculated  to  improve  the  genernl  functioning  of  the  economy.  In  some  cases,  of  course,  a  pattern  of 
seasonal  price  variation  which  was  originally  well-grounded  and  economically  desirable  may  become  some- 
what distorted  because  of  the  intrusion  of  irrational  elements.  The  price  of  styled  apparel,  for  example, 
seems  to  follow  a  fairly  predictable  seasonal  pattern.  Regardless;  of  thrir  original  basis,  however,  seasonal 
changes  in  style,  as  they  appear  in  our  modern  markets,  seem  to  be  far  less  matters  of  necessity  than  of  cus- 
tom. Frequently,  the  pattern  has  become  quite  illogical.  The  desire  to  be  the  first  to  display  a  new  mode 
has  been  so  exploited  that  seasons  are  rushed  to  a  very  marked  extent.  S[iring  apparel,  fcr  example,  is 
regularly  purchased  in  January,  February,  or  March,  rather  than  in  Ajjrilor  May.  As  a  result,  cold  weather 
in  January,  instead  of  stimulating  the  sale  of  winter  apparel,  may  actually  act  as  a  deterrent  to  the  production 
of  spring  linos. 

There  may  be  some  industries  which  do  not  now  reflect  any  di.stinct  pattern  of  seasonal  price  variation  and 
in  which  such  variation  might  conceivably  tend  to  .stimulate  sales  during  otherwise  dull  periods,  thus  per- 
mitting the  more  efhcient  use  of  productive  machinery.  For  example,  it  is  conceivable— though  far  from 
certain — that  seasonal  variations  in  the  demand  for,  say,  electric  refrigerators  might  be  reduced  if  prices  were 
slightly  lowered  during  the  winter  and  correspondingly  raised  during  tlie  spring. 

io  Of  course,  the  mere  fact  th.>it  the  price  movements  of  a  given  commodity  adequately  reflect  secular  in- 
fluences Is  only  one  criterion.  Responsiveness  to  change  is  no  guarantee  that  the  level  may  not,  at  all  timee 
be  out  of  line. 


i 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  23 

recovery  and  boom,  such  as  the  years  of  the  last  war  or  the  period 
1922-29. 

Striking  differences  are  apparent  in  the  behavior  of,  prices  of  dif- 
ferent commodities  during  these  periods.  For  example,  chart  I  depicts 
three  distinct  kinds  of  price  behavior.  The  price  of  sulphur,  it  will 
be  seen,  proved  to  be  entirely  inflexible.  It  changed  not  at  all  from 
the  year  1926  to  the  year  1938.  In  contrast,  the  price  of  wheat  is 
typical  of  the  behavior  of  most  highly  flexible  prices.  It  declined 
sharply  from  1929  to  1932-33,  recovered  rapidly  until  the  spring  of 
1937  and  then  again  declined  sharply.  Intermediate  between  these 
extremes  is  the  price  of  brick,  which  may  be  classed  as  semisensitive. 
It  responded  to  the  general  broad  upswings  and  downsvyings  of  business 
but  its  response  was  far  more  limited  than  that  of  the  pries  of  wheat. 

A  few  examples  of  the  behavior  of  specific  prices  may  illustrate  the 
relationship  between  these  four  kinds  of  influences  which  affect  prices, 
and  indicate  that  price  "flexibility,"  as  such,  can  have  no  meaning 
unless  its  specific  nature  is  considered. 

Chart  II  shows  monthly  variations  in  the  price  of  eggs  in  New  York 
since  1926.  Marked  swings  from  month  to  month  reveal  sensitivity 
to  immediate  or  casual  market  factors.  A  distinct  seasonal  pattern 
is  also  apparent,  with  lows  in  the  spring  and  summer,  and  highs  in  the 
late  fall  and  winter.  Responsiveness  to  cyclical  influences  is  re- 
flected by  a  marked  decline  in  price  from  1929  to  1932-33  and  again 
from  1936  to  1937.  Finally,  there  seems  to  be  a  broad  downtrend 
during  the  entire  period ;  the  recovery  highs  were  distinctly  lower  than 
the  corresponding  predepression  figures. 

The  price  of  cotton  goods  (chart  II)  exhibits  a  different  pattern, 
though  it,  too,  is  usually  classed  as  very  flexible.  It  is  highly  respon- 
sive to  cyclical  forces  and  there  is  some  evidence  of  a  persistent  long- 
term  downtrend.  On  the  other  hand,  casual  variations  are  minor  and 
there  is  no  apparent  seasonal  movement. 

Rayon  (chart  II)  experienced  a  major  secular  doAvntrend  between 
1926  and  1932;  during  the  latter  part  of  this  period  the  influence  of 
the  genei'al  cyclical  recession  may  have  been  superimposed  to  aggra- 
vate the  decline.  Secular  influences  probably  persisted  to  limit  the 
extent  of  recovery  between  1932  and  1937.  A  fairly  sharp  decline  (22 
percent)  between  1937  and  1938  may  well  have  been  largely  cyclical 
in  nature  concurrent  with  the  general  downswing  of  that  period. 

In  some  cases  there  may  be  marked  secular  movement  with  little 
if  any  sensitivity  to  the  general  level  of  business  activity.  Electric 
refrigerators,  phosphate  rock  and  potash  salts  (chart  III)  illustrate 
this  situation.  Yet  these  prices  differ  among  themselves  in  other 
important  aspects.  Refrigerators  had  a  sustained  downtrend  in  price 
extending  over  many  years,  reflecting  improved  technology  and 
widening  markets.  In  contrast,  price  reductions  for  phosphate  rock 
and  potash  salts  were  apparently  averted  for  a  long  period,  until  at 
last  the  accumulated  force  of  improved  methods  and  lower  costs  was 
reflected  in  each  case  in  abrupt  price  cuts  of  over  40  percent.^^  None 
of  these  three  commodities  shows  much  casual  variability,  while  potash 
salts  displays  a  distinct  and  consistent  seasonal  pattern. 

"  For  a  discns5lou  of  te^-hnological  changes  In  tlie  production  of  phosphate  rock,  see  rhojspbato  Rock 
Mining,  1880-1937,  Works  Progress  Administration,  National  Research  Project,  and  Department  of  tha 
Interior,  Bureau  of  Mines.    In  the  case  of  potash  salt^ne*-  scurccs  of  supply  were  an  important  factor. 


247149— 41— No.  1- 


24 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chabt  II 


25 


INDEX 
160 


140 
120 
100 
80 
60 
40 
20 
140 
120 
100 
80 
60 
40 
20 
0 
140 
120 


WHOLESALE   PRICES 

OF  SELECTED    COMMODITIES 

1926=100 
EGGS,  FIRSTS,  NEW   YORK 


COTTON    GOODS 


RAYON 


100 1- 
80 
60 
40 


20 


^ 

1 

1 

A 

i 

1/1 

i 

% 

^^ 

Wi 

^^    *tr  i 

!        1 

1 

1 

^ 

"\_ 

^ 

^-V^-U/v -V 

1926  1927  1928  1929  1930  1931    1932  1933    1934  1935   1936  1937   1938  1939 


INDEX 

160 


140 

120 

100 

80 

60 

40 

20 

140 

120 

100 

80 

60 

40 

20 

0 

140 

120 

100 

80 

60 

40 

20 

0 


UNireO     STATES     BUREAU     OP    LASOP     STATISTICS 


26 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


</> 

(0 

Li.1 

b 

< 

h- 

(/) 

O 

X 
(A) 

o 

^ 

:e 

O 
0. 

o 
o 


- 

•v. 

- 

f 

- 

C, 

- 

- 

V 

O          1 

9      ' 

:s 

I- 

-s  c; 

S5     r 

> 

"Si     "J 

N. 

-      Ij 

^ 

' 

I 

ii. 

- 

- 

- 

- 

) 

- 

o 

J 

r 

r  / 

- 

- 

^ 

- 

o 

LU 

O 
LU 

-J 
LJ 
CO 


CO 
LU 
O 

Q:: 
Gl 

LU 

-J 
< 
CO 
LU 


wOOOOOOOO 


- 

,. ....  J 

1    . 

i 

- 

c 

^ 

- 

- 

s 

- 

A 

. 

o 

- 

i  ^ 

8     O 
s     < 
I    a: 

- 

c 

- 

o 

1 

LJ 

I 

-o 
o 

'i 

3 

- 

-o 
o 

( 

> 

- 

T 

-2 

_ 

=      X 

.<J> 

J—' 

. 

Q. 

s    t- 

v^ 

(0 

- 

- 

"    ^ 

- 

f 

- 

O 

s    < 
i 

^ 

X 

• 

- 

- 

2 

i 

- 

f 

- 

o  o 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  27 

The  price  of  anthracite  coal  (chart  III)  has  remained  within  a 
much  narrower  range  during  the  period  between  the  summer  of  1926 
and  the  present  time  than  any  of  the  other  prices  shown.  However, 
it  shows  many  month-to-month  clianges  and  a  distinct  seasonal  swing. 
Over  the  entire  period,  secular  influences  are  revealed  in  a  steady 
downtrend.  Yet  the  depression  as  such  seems  to  have  had  but  little 
influence;  the  failure  of  prices  to  recover  since  1933  makes  it  probable 
that  the  1929-33  decline  was  part  of  a  long-term  readjustment  rather 
than  a  specific  response  to  the  contraction  of  general  business  activity 
during  that  period. 

Finally,  the  prices  of  some  commodities  are  subject  to  such  powerful 
specific  forces  that  the  influence  of  broader  economic  trends  is  com- 
pletely overshadowed.  This  is  illustrated  by  the  price  of  potatoes 
(chart  III).  Between  1930  and  1933,  potato  prices  roughly  paralleled 
the  behavior  of  other  highly  sensitive  prices,  although  the  downswing 
was  somewhat  delayed  and  the  upswing  extremely  rapid.  However, 
this  parallelism  may  have  been  largely  fortuitous;  the  chart  shows  at 
least  three  other  price  swings  of  approximately  equal  intensity  which 
bear  little  or  no  relation  to  the  trend  of  the  general  price  level  or  to  the 
rate  of  business  activity. 

These  few  illustrations  indicate  the  need  of  relating  the  problem 
to  a  specific  market  setting.  The  economic  significance  of  differences 
in  sensitivity  cannot  be  appraised  until  the  question  "sensitivity  to 
what?"  has  been  answered.  Accordingly,  it  should  be  emphasized 
that  the  following  discussion  is  concerned  chiefly  with  the  "cyclical" 
aspects  of  price  behavior,  or  with  the  responsiveness  of  prices  to 
broad  changes  in  the  rate  of  business  activity. 

THE    MEASUREMENT    OF    PRICE    FLEXIBILITY 

The  distinction  between  measures  of  behavior  and  oj  responsiveness. — 
Up  to  this  point  it  has  been  possible  to  treat  the  problem  alternatively 
as  relating  either  to  the  external  characteristics  of  price  behavior,  or 
else  to  the  responsiveness  of  prices  to  market  forces.  Howevej',  when 
the  possibilities  of  measuring  flexibility  are  examined,  it  becomes 
necessary  to  distinguish  between  the  two  courses. 

(1)  The  behavior  of  the  price  of  any  commodity  can  be  considered 
in  relation  to  the  specific  economic  forces  affectmg  its  market. 

(2)  The  movement  of  the  price  may  be  examined  on  a  purely  be- 
havioristic  level,  independently  of  the  specific  forces  aft'ecting  its 
market,  but  in  relation  to  the  pattern  of  behavior  for  other  prices. 

Of  these  two  approaches  the  former  is  in  many  ways  the  more  mean- 
ingful. The  behavior  of  any  price  cannot  be  fully  appraised  except 
in  the  light  of  a  detailed  analysis  of  the  factors  affecting  the  market 
for  that  commodity.  Although  it  is  true  that  during  major  upswings 
or  downswings  of  business  the  prices  of  almost  all  commodities  are 
subject  to  forces  acting  in  the  same  direction,  the  intensity  of  such 
forces  varies  very  materially  for  different  kinds  of  product.  In  some 
cases  the  specific  forces  may  even  overshadow  the  more  general,  caus- 
ing anomalies  of  price  behavior  which  cannot  be  explained  by  the 
examination  of  prices  alone.  Judgment  as  to  what  constitutes  eco- 
nomically desirable  behavior  for  the  price  of  any  commodity  must, 


28  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

therefore,  be  conditioned  by  the  forces  affecting  its  particular  market, 
and  cannot  depend  exclusively  upon  comparison  with  the  course  of 
other  prices. 

There  is  another  important  reason  for  measuring  flexibility  as  a 
function  of  the  factors  affecting  each  individual  market.  Responsive- 
ness to  changing  conditions  often  takes  the  form  of  modifications  in 
the  character  of  the  product  rather  than  in  its  price  as  such.  A  pro- 
gressive improvement  in  quality  is  in  some  ways  equivalent  to  a 
reduction  in  price.  For  example,  there  has  been  a  marked  improve- 
ment in  the  operating  efficiency  of  mechanical  refrigerators  over  a 
period  of  years.  This  is,  in  turn,  reflected  in  a  material  decrease  in 
current  consumption  per  unit  of  refrigeration.  If  the  consumer  is 
interested  in  purchasing  not  a  refrigerator  per  se  but  rather  a  certain 
amount  of  refrigeration,  this  improvement  in  efficiency  cannot  be- 
ignored.  In  other  cases  quality  betterment  or  quality  degradation 
may  not  be  as  readily  translatable  into  price  terms,  but  these  changes 
are  nevertheless  significant.  Consequently  it  is  only  part  of  the 
story  to  say  that  a  price  is  "rigid"  merely  because  it  shows  little  change 
in  level,  without  first  examining  modifications  in  the  product  itself.'^'^ 

.However,  there  are  very  serious  practical  difficulties  in  the  way  of 
developing  the  sort  of  relational  measures  of  flexibility  which  are 
implied  above.  An  analysis  of  the  relevant  market  factors,  product 
by  product,  for  all  the  items  included  in  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics 
wholesale  index,  for  example,  or  even  for  a  properly  representative 
selection  of  such  items,  is  a  herculean  undertaking.  Such  studies 
would  have  to  go  far  beyond  the  scope  usually  assigned  to  investiga- 
tions of  sensitivity.  Thus  chapter  IV  of  this  report  contains  an 
extended  analysis  of  the  markets  for  electrical  household  equipment; 
yet  much  more  data  would  be  needed  as  a  basis  for  appraising  the  price 
responsiveness  of  the  products  considered.  Moreover,  it  is  not  at  all 
certain  that  statistical  techniques  could  be  devised  to  express  such 
analyses  in  uniform  quantitative  terms  which  would  permit  a  com- 
parison of  the  results  for  different  kinds  of  products. 

For  the  time  being,  therefore,  and  because  most  of  the  discussion  of 
the  subject  has  followed  similar  lines,  the  alternative  procedure  has 
been  adopted  in  this  chapter;  that  of  measuring  price  flexibility  by 
examining  the  behavior  of  prices  without  reference  to  the  specific 
market  forces  at  work,  but  in  relation  to  the  behavior  of  other  com- 
modity prices.  The  significance  of  such  measures  is  twofold.  Similar- 
ities or  disparities  in  price  behavior  have  important  economic  signifi- 
cance and  consequences  in  their  own  right.  For  example,  they  exert 
a  marked  effect  upon  the  exchange  relationships  between  different 
groups  of  producers.  Thus  diversities  in  trend  between  the  prices  of 
farm  products  and  manufactured  goods  directly  influence  the  effective 
purchasing  power  of  fanners.  Such  effects  may  be  inferred  from  an 
examination  of  how  prices  act  without  reference  to  why  they  so  act. 

Secondly,  during  broad  upswings  and  down^swings  of  business  the 
prices  of  most  commodities  are  subject  to  powerful  forces  acting  in 
the  same  direction ;  for  example,  almost  all  markets  experience  a  cur- 
tailment of  demand  during  recession  and  an  expansion  of  demand 
during  recovery.     To  the  extent  to  which  there  is  such  similarity 

"  The  relationship  between  price  and  quality  changes  Is  discussed  at  more  length  In  ch.  Ill  of  this  report— 
Nonprlce  Competition. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  29 

between  the  forces  acting  upon  the  prices  of  different  commodities, 
price  behavior  as  such  may  be  considered  a  guide  to  price  responsive- 
ness. 

Almost  all  of  the  efforts  which  have  been  made  thus  far  to  prepare 
statistical  analyses  of  price  flexibility  have  been  content  with  this 
sort  of  external  approach.  Measures  have  been  applied  to  each  price 
series  without  relation  to  the  specific  market  factors  affecting  its 
behavior.  Thus  the  frequency  with  which  different  prices  changed 
and  the  relative  extent  of  their  declines  during  the  depression  of 
1929-33  have  been  compared  directly  without  any  correction  for  differ- 
ences in  basic  market  characteristics.  Because  of  the  importance 
attached  to  them  in  current  analysis  the  different  forms  of  such 
measures  are  examined  in  detail  below.  The  lunitations  just  discussed 
apply  to  all  of  them  and  must  be  constantly  borne  in  mind  in  their 
interpretation. 

The  specific  measures  utilized. — There  are  three  general  criteria  of 
flexibility  which  have  been  applied  to  prices. ^^     These  are — 

(1)  The  frequency  of  price  movement. 

(2)  The  amplitude  of  price  movement. 

(3)  The  timing  of  price  movement. 

All  of  these  have  been  utilized  at  various  times  in  previous  studies 
of  price  behavior.  Before  describing  these,  and  other  measures 
which  have  been  developed  in  the  course  of  the  present  study,  it  is 
pertinent  to  examine  the  economic  significance  of  each. 

The  frequency  with  which  any  particular  price  changes  (e.  g.,  the 
number  of  monthly  quotations  which  show  changes  from  the  imme- 
diately preceding  monthly  quotations  during  a  given  period — see 
criteria  A  and  B,  appendix  I) — has  restricted  usefulness  as  a  measure  of 
flexibility.  Assuming  the  accuracy  of  the  data,  it  may  serve  as  some 
index  of  the  responsiveness  of  the  price  to  casual,  very  short-term 
forces. 2^  To  an  extent  it  will  also  reflect  seasonal  variations.  How- 
ever, the  very  fact  that  this  measure  reflects  both  casual  and  seasonal 
variations  limits  its  value  as  a  measure  of  either  separately.  Fre- 
quency of  change  is  obviously  unsuited  to  measure  seasonal  flexibility 
because  of  the  extent  to  which  it  is  influenced  by  casual  movements. 
Conversely,  regular  seasonal  fluctuations  in  the  price  of  such  commodi- 
ties as  anthracite  coal  or  potash  salts  result  in  a  fairly  high  frequency 
of  change  in  their  monthly  price  quotations;  yet  their  sensitivity  to 
casual  market  factors  is  but  slight.  Conceivably,  the  use  of  seasonally 
adjusted  indexes  might  compensate  for  the  latter  defect. 

"  The  principal  statistical  measures  of  price  flexibility  which  have  been  devised  are  presented  below  under 
the  names  of  their  formulators: 

Frederick  C.  Aii7/4.— Frequency  of  Change;  Amplitude  of  Movement;  Measure  of  Price  Dispersion;  Meas- 
ure of  Displacement;  Timing  of  Cyclical  Phases. 

Oardiner  C.  A/eans.— Frequency  of  Change;  Amplitude  of  Change  (Percent  change  1929  to  1932);  Devia- 
tion Measured  from  Trends  (Average  1929-37)  to  1932. 

Oerhard  Tintner— Frequency  of  Monthly  Price  Changes;  Amplitude  of  Change;  Respo:ise  to  the  Average 
Cyclical  Movements. 

Edtcard  S.  Mason.— Average  Amplitude  of  Price  Change  (by  8-ycar  periods). 

Don  I himphre!/.— Frequency  of  Price  Change;  Amplitude  of  Change. 

'«  Limitations  related  to  the  time  intervals  for  which  data  have  been  tabulated  m.ust  not  be  ignored.  Thus, 
if  frequency  is  based  upon  a  comparison  of  successive  monthly  prices,  it  will  be  difliicult  or  impossible  to 
distinguish  between  those  prices  which  change  from  minute  to  minute,  such  as  wheat  or  cotton,  and  those 
whose  level  usually  remains  stable  for  days  or  perhaps  weeks,  such  as  print  cloth.  Yet  these  two  are  in  many 
ways  dififerent  kinds  of  markets. 


30  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Frequency  of  change,^'  then,  measures  directly  only  sensitivity  to 
short-term  influences;  not  to  cyclical  or  secular  forces.  It  is  of  value 
in  analyses  of  the  latter  only  to  the  extent  to  which  correlations  be- 
tween these  different  aspects  of  sensitivity  may  be  found  to  exist. 

The  measurement  of  cyclical  flexibilitv  may  be  approached  directly 
by  examining  the  extent  to  which  particular  prices  changed  during 
periods  of  general  business  upheaval.  The  percentage  by  which 
prices  declined  from  1929  to  1932-33,  the  percentage  of  recovery 
from  1932-33  to  1937,  or  perhaps  a  combination  of  both  these  move- 
ments would  fall  into  this  class,  (See  measures  C  to  I  in  appendix 
I.)  Here  again  there  are  certain  complicating  factors  other  than 
those  inherent  in  the  character  of  the  data.  One  of  these  is  the  fact 
that  secular  trends  may  be  operating  during  the  particular  period 
investigated  with  the  result  that  cyclical  movements  are  exaggerated 
or  perhaps  obscured.  Thus,  to  attribute  the  sharp  decline  in  the 
prices  of  electric  refrigerators  or  rayon  during  the  depression  purely 
to  the  influence  of  the  drop  in  general  business  activity  would  ignore 
the  influence  of  powerful  technological  forces  and  widening  markets 
to  which  the  behavior  of  these  prices  seems  largely  attributable. 
Nor  can  the  effect  of  seasonal  forces  be  neglected.  For  example,  in 
the  case  of  eggs  the  difference  between  the  1929  high  and  the  1933 
low  is  attributable  in  good  part  to  normal  seasonal  variation ;  cyclical 
factors  account  for  only  a  part  of  the  movement.  Moreover,  other 
specific  market  forces  are  often  present;  the  influence  of  a  drought, 
a  bumper  crop,  or  a  war  scare  might  affect  any  computation  designed 
to  determine  the  sensitivity  of  agricultural  products. 

Probably  seasonal  variation  could  be  allowed  for,^®  but  it  is  difficult 
to  devise  techniques  to  compensate  for  secular  or  short-term  forces  of 
the  kind  described. 

The  timing  of  price  movements,  e.  g.,  the  month  during  which  a 
sustained  uptrend  or  downtrend  began,  is  adapted  to  measuring 
certain  aspects  of  cyclical  flexibility  (see  measures  J  to  L,  appendix 
I).  However,  the  apparent  speed  of  responsemay  agam  be  obscured 
by  noncyclical  factors;  secular,  seasonal,  or  even  casual." 

The  reliability  of  all  of  these  measures  of  flexibility  is  of  course 
conditioned  by  the  accuracy  of  the  data  upon  which  they  are  based. 
The  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  indexes  of  wholesale  prices  have  been 
very  generally  utilized  in  computations  of  this  kind.  Limitations  on 
their  validity  for  this  purpose  have  been  recognized  by  the  Bureau 
and  have  also  been  analyzed  by  the  National  Resources  Committee  ^* 
in  connection  with  its  inquiries  into  prices.  It  has  been  pointed  out 
that  price  changes  are  not  always  fully  or  promptly  reported.     The 

"  In  all  this  it  is  assumed  that  frequency  of  change  is  measured  for  reasonably  short  time  intervals— e.  g., 
not  exceeding  monthly.  Obviously  frequency  computed  for,  say,  yearly  intervals  would  have  a  quite 
different  meaning. 

'•  This  might  be  done  by  comparing  annual  average  prices  only,  or  by  basing  the  measure  upon  the  same 
month  of  each  year,  or  by  introducing  a  seasonal  correction  into  the  price  index.  Two  such  measures  have 
been  developed  inr"the  course  of  the  present  study  and  are  presented  in  appendix  I  (measures  H  and  I). 

"  It  is  also  fiossible  to  devise  measures  which  combine  two  or  more  of  the  above  criteria.  For  example 
If  all  the  changes  in  price  experienced  by  a  commodity  during  a  given  interval  be  added  together  (regardless 
of  whether  any  specific  movement  be  up  or  down)  the  result  is  a  measure  of  aggregate  mov^ent  which 
Includes  elements  of  both  frequency  and  anii)litude  (measure  N,  appendix  I).  Another  possibility  is  the 
computation  of  the  average  amount  by  which  a  price  changes,  when  it  does  change  (measure  M,  appendix 
I).  Such  measures  as  these  seem  most  closely  related  to  responsiveness  to  casual,  or  seasonal  forces.  They 
are,  however,  also  subject  to  the  same  general  kind  of  objection  that  it  is  difficult  to  distinguish  between 
diverse  overlapping  movements. 

"  The  Structure  of  the  American  Economy,  pt.  I,  National  Resources  Committee,  June  1939,  appendix  I, 
pp.  173-185. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  31 

frequency  of  price  change  for  many  commodities  is  materially  greater 
than  would  be  inferred  from  an  examination  of  successive  nominal 
monthly  quotations.  Measures  of  amplitude  are  subject  to  the 
difficulty  that  price  reductions  during  depressions  often  take  the  form 
of  secret  rebates  or  indirect  concessions,  rather  than  of  outright  cuts 
in  quoted  prices. 

It  seems  apparent,  therefore,  that  measures  of  flexibility  based  upon 
comparisons  of  price  quotations  must  not  be  regarded  as  mathemat- 
ically accurate.  The  overlapping  influences  to  which  prices  are  sub- 
ject and  the  difficulties  in  the  way  of  obtaining  accurate  price  quota- 
tions constitute  serious  obstacles  to  their  reliability.  Nevertheless, 
some  of  the  statistical  relationships  observed  in  an  analysis  of  these 
measures  are  so  marked  and  so  consistent  that  they  cannot  be  con- 
sidered purely  fortuitous. 

MEASURES    OF    FLEXIBIIJTY    COMPARED 

Currently,  a  great  deal  of  attention  has  been  devoted  to  the  fre- 
quency of  price  change  as  a  correlative  of  cyclical  flexibility.^^  As 
pointed  out  earlier,  frequency  of  price  change  is  not  of  itself  a  direct 
measure  of  responsiveness  to  cyclical  influences.  However,  there 
seems  ample  evidence  that  those  prices  which  change  most  frequently 
also  tend  to  decline  farthest  during  a  depression,  and  that  those  which 
change  least  often,  usually  remain  most  stable. 

Much  of  the  work  in  this  field  has  been  done  by  Gardiner  C.  Means. 
In  a  report  prepared  for  the  Secretary  of  Agriculture  and  published  as 
a  Senate  Document,^  he  examined  750  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statis- 
tics indexes  of  wholesale  prices;  These  items  were  divided  into  10 
groups  depending  upon  the  frequency  with  which  monthly  price 
quotations  changed.  Average  monthly  prices  for  each  of  these  groups 
were  computed  and  a  fairly  consistent  relationship  demonsirated 
between  frequency  of  price  change  and  the  extent  of  decline  during 
the  1929-33  recession. 

Subsequently,  the  analysis  was  refined  and  carried  further.  The 
National  Resources  Committee  study  of  The  Structm-e  of  the  American 
Economy  ^^  depicts  the  average  price  trend  for  five  frequency  groups 
for  the  period  from  1913  to  the-  present.  The  correlation  between 
frequency  of  change  and  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  holds  for 
the  upswing  from  1933  to  1937  and  for  the  1937-38  downswing,  as 
weU  as  for  the  initial  depression  break.  It  is  also  apparent,  though 
to  a  lesser  degree,  for  price  movements  during  the*  war  boom  of  1915 
to  1919  and  the  subsequent  primary  deflation  of  1919  to  1921. 

In  the  course  of  the  present  study  exploratory  work  was  also  done 
in  the  direction  of  developing  alternative  measures  of  flexibility. 
Various  criteria  were  employed;  some  relating  primarily  to  shorter 
term  factors  and  others  designed  to  reflect  the  impact  of  cyclical  forces. 
They  included  frequency  of  change,  aggregate  movement  and  average 
amomit  of  price  change  during  a  period  of  relatively  high  business 

"  An  exhaustive  statistical  study  of  the  relationship  of  price  movements  to  the  business  cycle,  which  in- 
cludes data  on  price  movements  for  the  United  States,  England,  Germany,  Holland,  Austria,  and  Russia, 
is  fo  he  found  In  the  Austrian  publication,  Prices  in  the  Trade  Cycle,  1935,  by  Gerhard  Tintner,  translated 
and  obtainable  from  G.  E.  Stechert  &  Co.,  New  York  3ity. 

*"  S.  Doc.  No.  13,  74th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  Industrial  Prices  and  Their  Relative  Inflexibility,  January  17, 1935. 

»i  Op.  cit.,  p.  140. 


32  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

activity  (1926-29);  several  measures  of  amplitude  of  swing  between 
1929-33-37;  and  timing  of  price  change  at  three  critical  turning  points. 
These  are  described  in  detail  subsequently.  Comparison  of  the  results 
derived  shows  again  that  all  of  these  measures  are  distinctly  related 
(see  appendix  I).  In  some  cases  the  correlation  is  higher  than  in 
others,  but  the  evidence  seems  sufficient  to  demonstrate  the  point. 
It  may  be  assumed,  therefore,  that  there  are  certain  underlying  influ- 
ences whose'  effect  upon  the  responsiveness  of  prices  to  different  kinds 
of  forces  shows  a  degree  of  consistency  regardless  of  the  measures 
applied. 

A  particularly  striking  relationship  is  observed  between  frequency 
of  price  change  and  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement.  (The  Pearsonian 
coefficient  of  correlation  between  these  two  measures  for  615  price 
series  is+.77.)^^  It  may  be  inferred,  consequently,  that  sensitivity 
to  cyclical  forces  is  distinctly  related  to  sensitivity  to  shorter  term, 
casual  influences.^^  This  conclusion  holds  despite  the  fact  that  none 
of  the  measures  used  can  be  trusted  to  portray  the  effects  of  either  of 
these  factors  exclusively. 

FACTORS   AFFECTING   I  RICE    BEHAVIOR 

The  explanation  most  frequently  advanced  for  this  relationship 
between  frequency  and  amphtude  of  price  movement  draws  upon  the 
distinction  between  "market"  and  "policy  influenced"  prices  made 
earlier  in  this  chapter.^*  It  has  been  pointed  out  that  the  behavior  of 
prices  is  importantly  influenced  by  the  role  which  policy  decisions 
play  in  their  determination.  Gardiner  Means  showed  that  if  all 
wholesale  price  series  are  grouped  in  accordance  with  frequency  of 
price  change,  a  marked  U -shape  distribution  results;  that  is,  on  the 
basis  of  this  measure  they  are  either  highly  flexible  or  quite  inflexible. 
The  great  bulk  of  the  series  changed  either  less  than  24  times  or  more 
than  80  times  during  the  96-month  period  upon  which  the  comparison 
was  based.  In  other  words,  the  price  quotations  of  most  commodities 
change  either  once  or  more  almost  every  month  or  else  not  oftener 
than  three  times  per  year. 

This  tendency  of  prices  to  vary  either  very  often  or  rarely  is  strik- 
ing, even  after  all  due  allowance  has  been  made  for  the  inherent  in- 
accuracies of  the  data.  Two  essentially  different  kinds  of  price 
behavior  seem  involved.  It  may  be  reasonably  inferred  that  most 
prices  whose  quotations  change  at  short  intervals  are  of  the  "market 
dominated"  variety  and  that  those  whose  frequency  of  change  is  at 
the  other  extreme  are,  to  some  extent,  affected  by  price  policy  decisions 
of  individual  firms  or  groups  of  firms. 

In  other  words,  there  is  a  strong  presumption  that  a  price  which 
changes  infrequently  is  a  "policy  influenced"  price.  If  the  rigidity 
is  extreme,  the  presence  of  monopoly  or  of  monopolistic  practices  may 
be  suspected.  However,  there  is  no  necessary  relation  between  price 
rigidity  and  monopoly,  if  "monopoly"  is  used  to  denote  collusive  or 
coercive  devices  for  restraining  competition,  or  the  complete  domina- 

M  See  appendix  I,  p.  170.  The  criterion  of  frequency  is  the  one  developed  by  the  National  Rgsources  Com- 
mittee; that  for  depression  sensitivity  was  developed  by  the  present  study.  The  former  relates  to  the 
number  of  monthly  changes  between  1926  and  1933;  the  latter  to  amplitude  of  movement  between  1929-33-37. 

"  This  assumes  a  degree  of  similarity  between  the  cyclical  forces  acting  upon  diHeront  products..    During 
a  movement  so  broad  as  that  between  1929  ani  1937,  however,  such  an  assumption  seems  warranted. 
•  »*  See  pp.  13-15. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  33 

tion  of  a  market  by  a  single  concern.  While  there  is  a  distinct  ten- 
dency for  prices  subject  to  such  monopolistic  controls  to  change  infre- 
quently, it  by  no  means  follows  that  prices  which  change  infrequently 
are  necessarily  monopoHstic.  Moreover,  elements  of  monopolistic 
<;ontrol  (still  used  in  the  sense  above  specified)  may  be  present  even 
though  the  pattern  of  price  behavior  is  of  the  kind  usually  associated 
with  market  domination. 

It  may  clarify  the  issue  to  allude  briefly  again  to  the  Influence  of 
product  standardization  upon  price  behavior.^^  Some  commodities — 
e.  g.,  electrolytic  copper,  pig  iron  of  a  defined  composition,  66°  sulfuric 
acid — are  of  such  character  that  the  buyer  has  little  or  no  reason  for 
preferring  the  product  of  one  seller  to  that  of  another;  the  same  observ- 
ation applies  to  commodities  purchased  on  specifications.  Under 
such  circumstances,  appreciable  price  differences  between  rival  sellers 
in  the  same  market  cannot  long  exist.  This  applies  with  particular 
force  to  nominal  or  published  price  quotations.  Secret  rebates  or 
concessions  may  be  overlooked;  but  any  open  price  cut  made  by  one 
seller  is  almost  inevitably  met  by  his  competitors  ia  short  order. 

In  cormnodities  of  this  kind,  if  price  quotations  remain  stable  for 
extended  periods,  it  may  be  reasonably  assumed  that  all  competing 
producers  are  avoiding  price  changes,  at  least  nomiually.  This  com- 
monly reflects  the  existence  of  some  kind  of  modus  Vivendi  in  the 
industry,  whether  it  be  based  upon  the  domination  of  a  single  concern 
or  upon  coercion,  collusion,  or  price  leadership. 

In  the  case  of  differentiated  products,  where  the  merchandise 
offered  by  competing  sellers  is  not  readily  interchangeable,  buyers  are 
accustomed  to  distinguish  between  the  commodities  offered  by  rival 
sellers.  Whether  buyer  preference  be  based  upon  intrinsic  physical 
differences  or  merely  upon  intangible  factors  such  as  brand  prestige  is 
not  material  to  the  discussion.  The  important  point  is  that  factors 
other  than  price  are  involved  in  the  buyers'  selection.  Under  such 
•circumstances,  each  seller  is  to  some  extent  relieved  from  the  necessity 
of  meeting  immediately  eveiy  change  in  the  prices  quoted  by  his  rivals. 
The  precise  degree  of  this  immunity  necessarily  varies  with  a  large 
number  of  factors,  such  as  the  nature  of  the  commodity,  the  relative 
€ase  or  difficulty  which  buyers  face  in  making  objective  comparisons 
.between  competing  items,  the  extent  to  which  an  advertising  cam- 
paign has  been  successful  in  persuading  the  public  of  the  unique 
qualities  of  specific  brands,  and  so  on.  Moreover,  the  immunity  is 
never  more  than  partial.  If  price  differences  between  similar  items 
become  excessive,  buyers  will  ultimately  tend  to  shift  their  patronage.** 
Nevertheless,  it  is  apparent  that  each  seller  may,  for  months  or  longer, 
ignore  changes  in  his  competitors'  prices.  Consequently,  infrequent- 
price  changes  for  products  of  this  kind  do  not  necessarily  carry  the 
same  implications  as  those  suggested  for  standard  commodities.  A 
modus  Vivendi  may  oxist,  but  the  apparent  price  behavior  is  quite 
compatible  with  its  absence. 

Frequency  of  price  change,  th(3n,  is  not  only  a  direct  measure  of 
sensitivity  to  casual  market  influences,  but  also  a  symptom  of  the 
relative  influence  of  immediate  market  conditions  and  of  price  policy 

'•  Although  this  point  has  already  been  considered  (See  oh.  I,  pp.  6-8),  it  is  reviewed  here  for  clarity. 

"  Yet  in  some  fields,  the  tolerance  is  very  great.  Thus  widely  advertised  drug  products  frequently  sell 
for  three  to  five  times  as  much  as  their  unadvertised  equivalents  and  sometimes  the  differential  is  even 
wider.    See  for  example  pp.  80-81  and  also  pp.  308-379,  bolow. 


34  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  I'OWEU 

decisions  upon  the  manner  of  price  determination.  This  may  throw 
some  light  upon  the  correlation  previously  referred  to  between  fre- 
quency of  change  and  cyclical  price  sensitivity.  In  very  general  terms 
it  may  be  assumed  that  prices  with  high  frequencies  of  change,  whose 
movements  closely  follow  the  shifting  moods  of  the  market,  declined 
furthest  during  the  depression  and  rose  most  during  recovery.  Prices 
whose  infrequent  changes  reflect  some  degree  of  latitude  in  price 
policy  formulation,  declined  on  the  whole  less  sharply  and  rose  less 
abruptly. 

However,  this  generalization  is  subject  to  numerous  exceptions. 
If  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  wholesale  price  series  be  ranged  in 
order  of  percentage  of  decline  during  the  depression,  the  result  is  a 
continuous  distribution.  This  contrasts  with  the  sharp  discontinuity 
of  distribution  observed  in  the  frequency  analysis.  It  is  clear  that 
there  are  not  two  distinct  classes  of  price  responsiveness  to  cyclical 
influences,  but  rather  an  insensible  gradation.  Specific  conditions 
may  even  cause  flexible  prices  to  move  against  the  general  trend. 
Thus,  hops  ^^  whose  price  may  be  classed  as  "market  determined," 
showed  material  price  increases  between  1929  and  1933,  while  the 
price  of  potatoes — also  a  "market"  price — showed  only  a  slight 
decrease.  In  contrast,  many  prices  normally  classed  as  "policy 
influenced,"  e.  g.,  petroleum  and  carbon  black,  showed  very  sharp 
declines  during  the  same  period. 

The  tendency  of  the  "administered"  groups  of  prices  to  decline  loss 
sharply  during  the  depression  than  the  "market-dominated"  prices,  to 
the  extent  to  which  it  holds,  is  due  to  a  wide  variety  of  factors. 
These  have  been  the  subject  of  much  attention  during  recent  years  and 
are  far  too  numerous  and  complex  to  discuss  here  in  detail.  They  are 
summarized  below. 

(1)  To  some  extent  "market"  prices  on  the  one  hand,  and  "adminis- 
tered '  prices  on  the  other,  relate  to  dift'erent  kinds  of  commodities. 
The  former  are  typical  of  raw  materials  and  particularly  of  agricultural 
raw  materials,  while  the  latter  are  more  commonly  associated  with 
manufactured  products.  It  has  long  been  observed  that  the  price  of 
raw  materials  tends  to  fluctuate  somewhat  more  widely  than  is  true  of 
manufactured  products.  Many  explanations  have  been  suggested; 
some  emphasizing  dift'erences  in  cost  structures,  while  others  contrast 
the  large  number  of  farmers  selling  any  specified  product  with  the 
more  concentrated  industrial  markets. 

Thus,  it  is  frequently  contended  that  the  prices  of  manufactured 
goods  are  relatively  rigid  because  their  costs  of  production  contain 
a  larger  proportion  of  inflexible  cost  elements  (e.  g.,  labor,  interest, 
depreciation)  than  is  true  of  agricultural  products.  Moreover,  for 
the  small-scale  farmer  the  cost  of  labor  may  represent  to  a  considerable 
extent  the  cost  of  his  own  and  his  family's  efforts  rather  than  actual 
money  expenditure.  However,  this  explanation  does  not  appear 
adequate.  The  farmer  is  by  no  means  free  of  inflexible  cost  elements; 
mortgage  payments  and  taxes  are  obvious  examples.  It  seem^  much 
more  significant  that  the  manufacturer  is  freer  to  express  his  costs  in 
a  price  policy,  whereas  the  farmer  within  a  given  season  can  do  nothing 
but  harvest  his  crops,  if  they  will  yield  anything  beyond  the  cost  of 

«'  The  very  sharp  Increase  in  the  price  of  hops  during  1933  probably  reflected  the  legalization  of  beer,  but 
even  the  1932  level  was  higher  than  that  prevailing  In  1929. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  35 

harvesting.  It  may  well  be,  therefore,  that  too  much  stress  has  been 
laid  upon  the  nature  of  manufacturing  costs  as  an  explanation  of  the 
relative  inflexibility  of  the  prices  of  manufactured  goods.  For  any 
particular  commodity  at  any  given  time,  the  relationship  between 
costs  and  prices  is  far  less  precise  and  immediate  than  such  reasoning 
would  imply.  In  the  first  place,  it  is  rarely  possible  to  determine 
with  accuracy  exactly  what  the  cost  of  producing  a  given  article  is. 
In  most  industries  there  is  a  large  proportion  of  indirect  or  overhead 
costs,  whose  computation  and  allocation  to  specific  products  involves 
a  large  number  of  assumptions.  An  outstanding  problem  arises  from 
the  fact  that  costs  vary  shar])ly  with  sales  volume.  Consequently, 
any  calculation  of  costs  must  start  with  an  estimate  of  what  sales 
will  be  and  it  is  obvious  that  any  estimate  of  future  sales  may  vary 
widely  from  reality.  If  sales  are  larger  than  expected,  the  calculated 
cost  may  materially  exceed  the  actual;  if  sales  fall  short  of  the  esti- 
mate, the  calculated  cost  w411  be  too  low.  Moreover  the  price  charged 
will  itself  affect  costs,  since  a  lower  price  may  stimulate  sales  and 
thereby  result  in  cost  economies.  In  short,  cost  accounting  is  not  an 
exact  science  and  cost  estimates  are  only  one  of  the  elements  which 
a  concern  must  consider  in  framing  its  pricing  policy.'^  Rigid  prices 
cannot  be  explained  simply  by  referring  to  "rigid"  cost  structures. 

(2)  Those  sellers  or  groups  of  sellers  who  have  a  degree  of  freedom 
in  determining  price  policies  are  necessarily  guided  largely  by  con- 
siderations of  individual  advantage.  Their  primaiy  concern  as 
businessmen  is  with  their  own  profit  prospects;  they  cannot  bo  ex- 
pected to  weigh  the  effect  of  each  of  their  actions  upon  the  general 
economy.  Then,  too,  dictates  of  immediate  expediency  often  out- 
weigh longer  term  considerations,  particularly  during  periods  of  acute 
stress.  Stable  prices  have  many  apparent  advantages;  not  only  to 
sellers  but  often  to-industrial  buyers  as  well.  Planning  is  facilitated. 
The  mechanical  cost  of  announcing  a  price  change  for  products  having 
a  wide  distribution  is  often  a  serious  deterrent.^''  Moreover,  there  is  a 
fear  that  prices,  once  reduced,  are  difTicult  to  raise  again  when  con- 
ditions alter;  buyers  may  protest  less  against  a  stable  price  than  against 
a  ten  percent  increase,  following  a  ten  percent  cut. 

(3)  In  general,  the  individual  seller  can  expect  to  benefit  from  a 
price  cut  only  if  the  volume  of  his  sales  is  thereby  increased  by  an 
amount  sufficient  to  augment  his  net  profits  or  reduce  his  loss.  This 
postulates  a  very  considerable  increase  in  consumption  as  price 
declines — e.  g.,  a  high  degree  of  elasticity  of  demand.  There  are 
many  industries  in  which  consumption  docs  not  increase  materially 
when  price  declines — i.   e.,   demand  is  notably  inelastic.*"    This  is 

>'Tho  difRculty  of  dctormining  iiricc  on  the  basis  of  cost  computations  was  amply  deraonsfrated  under 
N.  R.  A.  Many  codes  contained  provisions  prohibiting  sales  below  cost  but  the  complexities  Involved  In 
measuring  costs  precisely  made  it  necessary  to  resort  tn  highly  arbitrary  definitions  of  cost  elements  In  order 
to  render  enforcement  practicable.  Where  such  arbitrary  definitions  were  rejected  by  N.  R.  A.  officials, 
the  code  provisions  became  virtually  meaningless. 

'•  J.  K.  Oalbraith  quotes  an  observation  made  by  Means  to  the  effect  that  the  expensc<nvolvcd  in  making 
a  price  change  under  modern  conditions  is  an  incentive  to  holding  price  constant.  "A  concern  with  Nation- 
wide  sales  outlets  must  make  certain  that  dealers  are  informed  of  the  change;  it  must  distribute  new  price 
schedules  and  provide  safeguards  against  'leaks'  as  well  as  risk  a  temporary  cessation  of  business  in  case 
there  is  such  a  'Icnk.'  It  must  also  recast  its  advertising  to  acquaint  the  public  with  the  change.  All  of 
the.'e  things  cost  money  and  all  of  this  expenditure  Is  avoided  if  prices  arc  allowed  to  stay  where  they  are." 
(J.  K.  Oalbraith,  loc.  cit..  p.  470.) 

<"  The  drmnnd  curve  for  in'Iivdual  concerns  may,  of  course,  bo  quite  elastic  in  the  sense  that  material 
shifts  in  patronage  can  be  Induced  by  cutting  prices  below  the  level  quoted  by  competitors.  Flowevcr, 
there  is  a  tendency  among  businessmen  to  consider  such  advantages  purely  ephemeral,  because  of  the 
probability  liiat  such  reductions  will  almost  immediately  be  met  or  bettered,  with  no  significant  increase  in 
volume  for  the  industry  as  a  whole.  Consequently,  for  some  purposes,  elasticity  as  related  to  Iha  total 
market  for  a  product  is  more  significaui  than  elasticity  for  the  Individual  concern. 


36  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

true  particularly  of  those  industries  whose  product  is  merely  a  minor 
component  part  of  a  finished  article  manufactured  by  others,  of  whose 
total  cost  they  comprise  but  a  small  part.  Thus  the  consumption  of 
cement  depends  upon  the  rate  of  construction  activity,  the  demand 
for  spark  plugs  is  dependent  upon  the  sale  or  use  of  automobiles,  and 
so  on.  Consequently  an  isolated  change  in  the  price  of  such  com- 
modities cannot  be  expected  to  exercise  any  appreciable  influence 
upon  their  demand.  Sometimes  price  reductions  may  even  cause 
buyers  to  postpone  purchases  in  the  hope  of  further  reductions  and 
reduce  the  volume  of  activity  until  price  stability  is  achieved.  It  may 
be  true,  however,  that  businessmen  as  a  group  tend  to  underestimate 
the  degree  of  elasticity  characterizing  their  respective  markets.  In 
any  event  when  purchasing  power  is  curtailed  during  a  depression, 
businessmen  are  likely  to  favor  maintaining  price  as  the  technique 
best  adapted  to  minimize  losses.  The  reduction  of  prices  in  an  effort 
to  increase  volume  often  seems  to  them  as,  at  best,  an  uncertain 
adventure  at  a  time  when  undue  hazards  should  be  avoided.^^ 

(4)  The  propaganda  conducted  by  trade  associations  and  others  to 
convince  businessmen  of  the  undesirability  of  cutting  prices  has 
undoubtedly  affected  business  psychology. ^^  Price  cuts  are  often 
shunned  as  unethical  even  when  material  advantages  can  be  antici- 
pated from  a  lower  price  level. ''^  (This  does  not  relate  only  to  the 
ephemeral  advantages  which  a  firm  might  obtain  by  cutting  prices 
before  its  competitors,  but  also  to  those  which  might  be  retained  after 
competitors  had  adjusted  their  prices  to  the  new  level.)  Such  price 
cutting  as  does  take  place  usually  takes  the  form  of  more  or  less  secret 

«i  T.J.  Krcps  suggests  three  reasons  explaining  why  "rigid  prices  are  the  easiest  prices."  (1)  "By  changing 
and  especially  permitting  prices  to  be  lowered,  producers  increase  the  risi<  that  someone  will  try  to  'get  the 
jump'  on  the!  rest  and  attract;  customers  by  lowering  or  not  raising  prices  with  ensuing  damages  to  the 
profits  of  all  far  greater  than  the  temporary  losses  caused  by  restricted  sales  at  maintained  prices."  (2)  "If 
the  number  of  sales  outlets  is  large,  the  complexities  of  introducing  price  changes  and  of  getting  them  ac- 
cepted by  the  buying  publiC;  in  addition  to  the  distribution  of  new  price  schedules,  will  cost  money  and 
bother  so  easily  saved  by  'letting  good  enough  alone.'  "  (3)  "Sound  business  policy  demands  that  producers, 
especially  in  periods  of  slack  demand,  minimize  their  risks  and  conserve  their  working  capital.  Acceptance 
of  low  sales  volume  is  not  only  easier  but  may  mean  smaller  inventory  losses  due  to  fluctuating  prices." 
(Economic  Problems  in  a  Changing  World,  a  symposium,  Farrar  &  Rhinehart,  1939,  pp.  281-282.) 

«»  Notice  of  this  propaganda  and  dissent  to  it  was  recorded  in  a  recent  issue  of  the  business  journal.  Ad- 
vertising and  Soiling.  , 

"During  the  past  few  months  a  number  of  business  papers  and  trade  associations , have  conducted  a  cam- 
paign against  manufacturers  and  middlemen  who  practice  price  cutting. 

"It  must  be  admitted,  from  the  immediate  point  of  view,  that  this  campaign  may  prove  profitable.  It 
may  slow  down  price  declines  and  thus  allow  sellers  an  oppnrtpnity  for  gradual  litjuidation  of  their  stocks 
at  higher  prices.  Any  such  campaign,  however,  is  definitely  to  be  condemned  from  the  social  point  of 
view  and  even  from  a  long-run  view  point  of  manufacturers  and  middlemen. 

"In  view  of  increasing  unemployment  and  wage  cuts,  the  maintenance  of  prices  at  the  present  time  must 
mean  a  further  decrease  iti  the  consumption  of  goods  This  in  turn  w  ill  lead  to  a  further  contraction  in 
employment— this  to  a  still  greater  fall  in  consumption— more  unemployment— and  so  on. 

"The  present  pleading  to  maintain  prices  is  a  clear  cut  expression  of  the  policy  of  industry  to  adjust  Itself 
to  decrease  in  demand  by  cutting  production  rather  than  by  reducing  prices.  Such  a  policy  leads  to  a 
longer  period  of  economic  maladjustment — and  hence  creates  a  longer  period  in  which  the  ba<:inessman  may 
lose  money.    If  persisted  in,  it  may  lead  to  as  complete  a  break-down  as  in  1932. 

"It  needs  to  be  emphasized  that  it  is  the  price  cutter  who  is  paving  the  way  te  recovery.  He  is  putting 
merchandise  on  sale  at  prices  the  public  is  willing  and  able  to  pay.  This  not  only  encourages  more  con- 
sumption but  an  immediately  higher  standard  of  living.  It  also  results  in  reduced  inventories  in  the 
hands  of  retailers — which, in  turn,  depletes  inventorie;;  in  the  hands  of  wholesalers  and  manufacturers     •   •    • 

"For  a  real  recovery,  purchasing  power  must  arise  out  of  production  rather  than  out  of  Oovernment 
speeding.  'The  price  policies  adopted  by  manufacturers,  wholesalers,  and  ret.iilers  over  the  next  few  months 
will  have  much  to  do  with  how  far  the  Oovernment  will  be  forced  to  go  with  its  spending  program  to  stimu- 
late buying.  Businessmen  profess  to  fear  Government  spending.  If  they  want  to  stop  it,  let  them  adopt 
adequate  price  policies.  At  the  present  time  business  leaders  might  clear  the  stage  for  such  policies  by 
checking  indiscriminate  condemnation  of  the  price  cutter.  Th<'y  might  even  find  it  to  their  long-run 
advantage  to  adopt  price  catting  themselves."    (Advertising  and  Selling,  June  1938.) 

"  This  attitude  relates  primarily  to  price  cutting  for  the  purpose  of  obtaining  some  immediate  competi- 
tive advantage,  and  not  to  price  reductions  reflecting  cost  economies  due  to  such  factors  as  changes  in  tech- 
nology.   The  latter  variety  of  price  reductions  are  generally  considered  perfectly  ethical. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  37 

concessions.  When  price  competition  cannot  be  avoided,  this  form 
seems  to  be  considered  more  desirable  than  one  in  which  the  nominal 
quotations  are  affected.  It  probably  has  somewhat  the  same  advan- 
tages which  the  undeclared  war  has  in  international  politics.  It  is 
simpler  to  restore  normal  conditions  when  the  fray  has  subsided;  the 
subsequent  elimination  of  miofficial  concessions  is  likely  to  meet  less 
buyer  resistance  than  an  increase  in  the  nominal  quotation.** 

PRICES  AND  PRODUCTION 

For  such  reasons  as  those  just  discussed,  price  reductions  during 
periods  of  depressed  business  activity  are  likely  to  be  materially  smaller 
in  those  industries  in. which  individual  sellers  are  able  to  exert  some 
voice  hi  vletermining  the  course  of  prices,  than  in  those  in  which  imme- 
diate market  influences  are  the  dominant  factor. 

In  appraising  the  consequences  of  this  behavior,  there  is  probably 
no  single  phase  which  has  been  the  subject  of  more  discussion  and 
controversy  than  its  effect  upon  production  during  periods  of  economic 
recession.  Basically,  the  issue  is  drawn  in  these  terms.  When  for  any 
reason  purchasing  power  is  severely  curtailed,  the  market  must  make 
some  adjustment  to  the  reduced  amount  of  dollars  available  for  expen- 
diture. This  adjustment  will  take  the  form  partly  of  reductions  in 
price  and  partly  of  contraction  in  sales.  These  two  adjustments  may 
be  considered  complementary.  If  the  amount  available  for  expendi- 
ture at  any  time  be  considered  constant,  then /or  the  economy  as  a  whole 
it  follows  that  a  smaller  adjustment  in  price  will  require  a  greater 
adjustment  in  output. 

As  a  very  broad  generalization,  subject  to  allowance  for  such  factors 
as  changes  in  the  amount  of  hoarding,  this  is  undoubtedly  true.  In 
discussions  of  price  flexibility,  however,  the  issue  is  usually  formulated 
in  much  more  specific  terms.  It  is  argued  that  rigidities  in  certain 
areas  of  the  economy  cause  the  burden  of  adjustment  in  those  areas 
to  fall  heavily  upon  production;  that  is,  that  the  output  of  such  com- 
modities, and  employment  opportunities  in  their  production,  are  cur- 
tailed much  more  sharply  than  would  be  true  if  their  prices  were  mo^e 
flexible.*^  However,  this  point  of  view  has  been  vigorously  challenged. 
It  has  been  contended  that  price-production  relationships  are  not  as 
simple  as  this,  and  that  during  a  severe  depression  the  consumption 

"  This  has  recently  happened,  for  example,  in  the  steel  industry.  During  the  spring  and  summer  of 
1939  concessions  estimated  to  average  $6  per  ton  had  been  widely  granted;  after  the  outbreak  of  war  inEurope 
these  concessions  were  withdrawn,  resulting  in  an  important  increase  in  actual  prices  paid  for  steel.  Yet 
the  companies  in  the  industry  were  able  to  announce  that  price  quotations  were  unchanged  and  thereby 
to  escape  much  resistance  and  criticism. 

"  Thus,  according  to  Gardiner  0.  Means,  "One  can  make  the  broad  generalization,  having  of  course  many 
exceptions,  that  for  industries  in  which  prices  dropped  most  during  the  depression  production  tended  to 
drop  least,  while  for  those  in  which  prices  were  maintained  the  drop  in  production  was  usually  greatest. 
Indeed,  the  whole  depression  might  be  described  as  a  general  dropping  of  prices  at  the  flexible  end  of  tho 
price  scale  and  a  dropping  of  production  at  the  rigid  end  with  intermediate  effects  between    •    •    *. 

"The  adjustment  of  production  instead  of  price  in  the  inflexible  areas  aggravates  the  initial  price  adjust- 
ment in  the  flexible  industries  by  reducing  purchasing  power  and  throws  the  burden  of  further  price  adjust- 
ment on  the  flexibly  priced  commodities.  This  situation  can  be  clearly  seen  in  the  effect  of  the  depression 
upon  agricultural  prices  and  the  destruction  of  the  price  relationship  between  agricultural  and  industrial 
goods.  It  is  also  seen  in  the  fact  that  during  the  depression  tho  total  income  of  all  farmers  and  the  total  in- 
come of  all  industrial  workers  dropped  in  approximately  the  Fame  pro[iortion,  but  the  drop  in  farm  income 
reflected  a  drop  in  pricrs  while  the  drop  of  workers'  income  reflected  primarily  loss  of  employment."  Indus- 
trial Prices  and  Their  Relative  Flexibility,  op.  cit.,  pp.  9  and  25.) 


38 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


of  many  commodities  would  be  stimulated  little,  if  at  all,  by  further 
price  reductions.*® 

When  the  relationship  between  prices  and  production  declines  dur- 
ing recession  is  examined  commodity  by  commodity,  no  strikingly 
consistent  trend  is  revealed.  Chart  IV  illustrates  this  relationship 
for  111  commodities*^  for  the  1929-33  downturn.  The  percentage 
change  in  average  annual  price  for  each  of  these  products  is  plotted 
against  percentage  decline  in  production,  adjusted  for  imports  and 
exports.  The  three  sections  of  the  chart  distinguish  between  products 
on  the  basis  of  durability,  showing  three  categories  of  goods — durable, 
semidurable,  and  nondurable. 

An  examination  of  this  chart  reveals  the  following  relationships: 

(1)  Considering  all  the  commodities  together,  there  is  some  tend- 
ency for  small  declines  in  price  to  be  connected  with  large  declines  in 
production  and  vice  versa.  (The  Pearsonian  coefficient  of  correlation 
is  —0.32;  the  standard  error  of  this  coefficient  is  0.09.) 

(2)  For  nondurable  goods  alone  there  is  a  similar  broad  tendency. 
(The  coefficient  of  correlation  is  —0.44;  standard  error  0.12.) 

(3)  For  durable  goods  and  semidurable  goods  considered  separately, 
there  is  little  if  any  evidence  of  such  a  relationship.  (Coefficients  of 
correlation  are  —0.12  and  +0.01  respectively;  standard  error  in  each 
case  0.18.) 

(4)  There  was  a  marked  tendency  for  increasing  durability  to  be 
associated  with  smaller  declines  in  price  and  greater  curtailments  of 
production.  As  shown  by  the  following  table,  the  median  price  de- 
cline for  nondurable  items  was  substantially  greater  than  for  the 
durable.  The  sLx-percent  curtailment  in  production  for  the  former 
group  contrasts  strikingly  with  the  Gl -percent  curtailment  for  the 
latter. 


Table  1. — Median  change  in  price  and  quantity  available  for  consumption  1929-32, 
for  111  commodities,  classified  according  to  durability 


Type  of  commodity 

Number 
of  items 

Price 

Produe 
tion 

Durable                             --  

31 
32 
48 

-21 
-27 
-33 

-61 

-16 

-6 

<'  This  point  of  view  is  expressed  in  a  recent  bulletin  of  the  National  Industrial  Coufereneo  Board: 
"An  analysis  of  the  available  data  indicates  that  no  simple  and  clear  cut  relationship  prevails  between 
speciflc  commodity  price  and  production  changes.  Within  very  broad  limits  there  is  evident  some  tendency 
for  inflexible-priced  products  to  be  accompanied  by  greater  decreases  in  production  than  those  which  svere 
more  responsive  to  the  impact  of  outside  forces  But  the  relationship  is  not  so  close,  nor  so  surely  accounted 
for,  as  to  warrant  the  general  conclusion  that  sharp  reductions  for  particular  inflexible  prices  would  have  been 
effective  in  maintaining  demand,  and  hence  the  output,  for  these  products.  Certainly  it  seems  unlikely 
that  this  result  could  have  been  achieved  in  connection  with  capital  goods,  the  demand  for  which  is  deter- 
mined largely  by  the  outlook  for  future  prefits  rather  than  by  the  current  cost  of  new  capital  equipment — 
especially  during  times  of  depression  when  the  demand  schedule  for  such  goods  become,s  extremely  inelastic. 
That  factors  other  than  price  may  be  of  paramount  importance  is  indicated  by  the  t<>ndency  for  durable 
goods  to  record  the  larger  declines  in  production  and  for  nondurable  goods  to  show  the  smaller  declines, 
regardless  of  the  respective  changes  in  price.  The  postponablc  nature  of  the  demand  for  durable  goods  is  a 
familiar  phenomenon  which  furnished  a  more  logical  explanation  for  the  production  behavior  of  many 
floods  than  does  the  extent  of  price  decline."  (Price  Flexibility  and  Changes  in  Production,  Conference 
Board  Bulletin,  vol.  XIII,  No.  5,  February  20,  1039,  p.  51.) 

*' The  following  basis  was  used  in  selecting  these  111  commodities.  The  throe  most  heavily  weighted 
items  in  each  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  wholesale  price  subgroup  were  taken,  except  for  some  subgroups 
In  which  (lata  were  available  for  only  one  or  two  commodities.  The  purpose  of  this  procedure  was  to  insure 
a  fairly  representative  sample  covering  all  the  sectors  of  industry  for  which  wholesale  price  data  were 
available. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chabt  IV 


39 


CHANGE  IN  AVERAGE  WHOLESALE  PRICE  AND 

QUANTITY  AVAILABLE  FOR  CONSUMPTION 

111  COMMODITIES-  1929  TO  1933 

PERCENTAGE 
AVERSE  PRICE                                        DURABLE    GOODS                                         average  reicE 

0 

• 

V 

-10 

. 

-10 

-2Q 

*     •           ^         *.     . 

-20 

-30 

.    • 

-30 

-40 

• 

-40 

-50 

• 

-50 

-60 

. 

-60 

••70 

• 

-70 

80 

, 

-fin 

< 

0    -90     -60     -70     -60     -50    -40     -30     -20     -10        0        10        20       30      40      50      60      70 

AVERAGE 
0 

PRICE                                     SEMI-DURABLE    GOODS                                    averagemice 

■                                              T 

v-* 

,     • 

-10 

• 

-10 

-20 

• 

• 

-20 

-30 

+ 

; 

-30 

-40 

•                                           •                                                        , 

-40 

-50 

* 

* 

-50 

-60 

• 

-60 

-7  0 

• 

■ 

-70 

-80 

-80 

*^"c 

0    -90    -80     -70    -60     -50    -40     -30     -20     -10        0        10       20      30      40      50      60      7 

0 

AVERAGE 

0 

-10 

'^'^^                                   NON-DURABLE    GOODS                                   ^"^""^ 

E  PRICE 

0 
-10 

'                  ^ 

■ 

-2  0 

• 

• 

-20 

-30 

•     *                     +. 

*• 

-30 

-40 

• 

/ 

-40 

-50 

•     •     •     .*        • 

•. 

-50 

-60 

• 

* 

-60 

-70 

- 

-70 

-80 



-80 

10 

0  -90  -80   -70  -60   -50  -40   -30  -20    -10      0      10     20     30    40     50    60    7( 

AMOUNT    AVAILABLE    FOR    CONSUMPTION 

D 

-f     INOtCATES    THE  POSITION  OF  -THE  MEDIAN  CHANGE  FOR  EACH  GROUP  OF  COMMODITIES 

SOURCES     PERCENTftSES  COMPUTED  BY  THE  BUREAU  OF  LABOR  STATISTICS  AND  THE  BUREAU  OF  AGRICULTURE 

US  BUREAU  OF  LABOR  STTATISTICS                                        economics  from  data  coulecteo  by  these  and  other  government  agencies       .                    |j 

247149—41 — No.  1- 


40  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Great  caution  must  be  used  in  inferring  any  causality  from  these 
relationships.  The  fact  that  there  was  a  tendency  for  production  to 
be  curtailed  more  sharply  for  those  commodities  whose  price  declined 
less,  does  not  necessarily  imply  that  production  fell  because  prices 
were  maintained.  Conversely,  the  fact  that  for  durable  goods  (or 
equally  for  semidurable  goods)  taken  as  a  separate  group,  there  was 
no  appreciable  correlation  between  price  and  production  for  individual 
commodities,  does  not  necessarily  imply  that  the  two  were  unrelated. 

Consider  first  the  very  sharp  curtailment  in  the  production  of 
durable  goods  as  contrasted  with  the  well  maintained  output  of  non- 
durable commodities.  It  would  be  clearly  erroneous  to  attribute  this 
contrast  entirely  or  perhaps  even  primarily  to  the  correlative  differ- 
ence in  price  behavior.  Durable  goods  by  definition  are  purchased  to 
satisfy  future  as  well  as  present  wants;  an  automobile  is  bought  to 
furnish  not  only  immediate  transportation  but  also  transportation  for 
years  to  come.  But  when  purchasing  power  is  sharply  curtailed,  con- 
sumers perforce  ration  their  buying  and  emphasize  nondurable  com- 
modities such  as  foods  required  for  immediate  consumption.  Certain 
necessities  of  life  must  be  obtained  whether  their  price  be  high  or  low. 
Rents  and  taxes  and  certain  debts  must  be  paid.  If  anything  is  left 
after  thfese  expenditures  then,  and  only  then,  can  purchasing  power 
be  utilized  for  optional  or  marginal  uses,  such  as  luxuries  or  postponable 
replacements  of  durable  goods.  This  principle  applies  not  only  to  the 
ultimate  consumer  but  also  to  the  industrial  buyer,  and  the  unat- 
tractiveness  of  investment  further  limits  expenditures  for  capital 
goods. 

Thus,  if  a  product  is  an  absolute  necessity,  its  consumption  and  pro- 
duction may  remain  stable  even  though  its  price  fails  to  reflect  the 
decline  in  general  business  activity.  This  is  true,  for  example,  of 
domestic  salt;  sales  remained  stable  through  the  depression  while 
prices,  with  the  exception  of  one  or  two  short  flurries,  tended  mod- 
erately upward  instead  of  downward.  On  the  other  hand,  the  con- 
sumption of  items  whose  purchase  could  be  postponed  inevitably 
declined.  Price  reductions  might  cushion  but  could  not  prevent  a 
drop  in  sales.  Production  of  leather  gloves,  for  example,  dropped  58 
percent  between  1929  and  1933,  even  though  prices  fell  35  percent. 
Similarly,  the  price  of  water  closets  fell  45  percent  during  this  period; 
yet  a  concurrent  45-percent  drop  in  production  occurred  nothwith- 
standing.** 

It  happens  that  the  severest  price  declines  during  the  depression 
occurred  in  precisely  those  industries  which  produced  the  most  urgent 
necessities  of  life,  while  the  smallest  declines  were  to  be  found  among 
those  commodities  whose  purchase  could  best  be  deferred.  The  prices 
of  farm  products,  foods,  and  textile  products  all  dropped  more  than  40 
percent  between  June  1929  and  February  1933.  During  the  same 
period  the  prices  of  metals  and  metal  products,  house-furnishing  goods 
and  building  materials  fell  about  25  percent.  To  an  appreciable 
extent,  therefore,  the  fact  that  the  production  of  the  former  group  was 
curtailed  much  less  severely  than  that  of  the  latter,  reflected  differences 
not  so  much  in  their  price  behavior  as  in  the  needs  which  they  are 
designed  to  satisfy  and  the  way  in  which  they  are  produced  and  manu- 
factured.    The  consumption  of  urgently  needed  items  was  maintained 

*•  Specific  forces  undoubtedly  influen  ced  the  price  behavior  of  these  two  commodities  during  this  period. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


41 


primarily  because  the  items  were  urgently  needed  and  not  because  their 
prices  as  a  rule  declined.  Conversely,  consumption  of  items  designed 
to  satisfy  postponable  wants  declined  because  they  were  postponable 
and  not  merely  because  their  prices  were  maintained. 

Nor  is  it  valid  to  attribute  the  maintenance  of  agricultural  produc- 
tion wholly  to  the  sharp  drop  in  agricultural  prices  (see  chart  V) 
merely  because  the  two  were  concurrent  phenomena.  In  the  first 
place,  most  agricultural  products  entered  into  finished  goods,  such  as 
food  or  clothing  whose  purchase  cannot  be  indefinitely  deferred  *^  so 
that  a  well-sustained  level  of  sales  was  to  be  anticipated.     Of  perhaps 


Chart  V 


FARM   PRODUCTS 

PRICES    AND  PRODUCTION 

INOE)' 

140 

1926 

1 

=  100 

NOEX 

140 

»20 

100 

1 

— *^^^ 

=\ 

^'^ 

PRC 

DUCT 

ON 

^ 

/~" 

•^^ 

120 
100 

1 

I         80 

i 

;              j 
i 

\ 

/ 

7- 

•^ 

h^ 

\ 

80 
60 
40 

1 

40 

1 

!     ; 

V 

^ 

'\»i 

CE 

1         20 
0 



20 

1926    IS27    1928    1929  1930    1931    1932  1933    !934  1935  1936   1937    1938  1939 

1                                                                                                                                                                                                    SOOBCE -                                                                                                           1 

;  a  s  euREAu  of  labor  statistics                                                                                        proouction    department  of  agriculture                  1 

greater  importance,  moreover,  is  the  supply  side  of  the  equation.  The 
nature  of  the  agricultural  process  and  of  agricultural  markets  is  such 
that  curtailment  of  production  is  difficult  to  achieve.  For  the  small 
farmer,  a  sharp  reduction  in  output  simply  means  partial  disemploy- 
ment  for  himself  and  his  family.  It  is  noteworthy  that,  for  the  past 
40  years,  there  has  never  been  more  than  a  15-percent  reduction  in 
cotton  acreage. 

It  must  be  recognized  then  that  for  each  individual  commodity,  price 
is  but  one  of  the  factors  determining  its  level  of  production.  Post- 
ponability  of  demand  must  certainly  be  considered.  The  nature  of 
the  productive  process  is  important.     The  effect  of  price  changes  upon 

*•  This  refers  to  entire  classes  of  goods,  not  to  substitution  within  classes  such  as  the  use  of  one  kind  of  food 
In  place  of  another. 


42  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

production  is  necessarily  different,  too,  for  products  whose  demand  is 
joint  than  for  those  whose  demand  is  independent. 

It  is  apparent,  however,  that  any  appraisal  of  the  influence  of  price 
policies  upon  production  must  pay  due  regard  to  the  interrelated 
character  of  the  economy.  The  effect  of  a  change  in  price  for  any 
single  commodity  upon  its  production  is  influenced  by,  and  in  turn 
influences,  the  markets  for  many  other  commodities. 

Thus,  if  it  be  assumed  that  the  demand  for  some  necessity  of  life  is 
completely  inelastic,  its  price  may  still  have  a  material  influence  upon 
the  amount  of  money  consumers  will  have  available  for  more  optional 
expenditures.  The  production  of  these  less  urgently  needed  items 
would  thereby  be  directly  affected.  For  example,  if  the  price  of 
cigarettes  had  declined  further  during  the  depression,  it  is  doubtful 
whether  the  consumption  of  cigarettes  would  have  been  materially 
increased.  On  the  other  hand,  the  savings  realized  by  the  consumer 
might  have  served  to  stimulate  production  in  other  lines.  In  this 
particular  case  the  amount  involved  might  be  small,  but  the  principle 
is  significant. 

Considerations  of  this  sort  are  not  confined  to  the  action  of  com- 
modity prices.  It  is  estimated  that  about  one-third  of  total  consumer 
expenditures  are  for  services  of  all  kinds.^°  Such  items  as  rents, 
taxes,  interest  on  mortgages,  utilities,  professional  and  business  serv- 
ices therefore  account  for  a  very  substantial  fraction  of  the  consumer's 
budget.  Many  of  these  must  be  classed  as  necessities,  just  as  surely 
as  food  and  clothing.  Consequently,  their  prices,  too,  exercise  a 
distinct  effect  upon  the  demand  for  and  production  of  postponable  or 
nonessential  commodities. 

In  the  same  way  an  appraisal  of  the  effect  of  price  changes  upon 
the  consumption  of  commodities  subject  to  joint  demand  cannot  rest 
upon  an  industry-by-industry  approach.  It  is  true  that,  all  other 
things  being  equal,  a  change  in  the  price  of  bricks  or  steel  or  cement 
cannot  be  expected  to  exert  much  influence  upon  the  demand  for  these 
products.  However,  if  the  prices  of  aU  buildiQg  materials  were  reduced 
simultaneously  there  might  be  an  appreciable  increase  in  the  volmne 
of  construction  and  in  the  demand  for  each  of  these  commodities. 
The  effect  would  be  enhanced  still  further  if  the  costs  of  building 
financing  *^  and  of  construction  labor  were  correspondingly  modified. 
Although  an  isolated  change  in  any  one  factor  cannot  be  of  more  than 
limited  significance,  a  concurrent  change  in  many  factors  would  have 
a  very  far-reaching  influence. 

It  is  for  this  reason  that  a  mere  plotting  of  price  and  production 
data,  industry  by  industry,  upon  a  correlation  chart  can  yield  little 
of  significant  value  to  the  discussion.  The  effect  of  price  changes  for 
any  single  item  is  not  spent  exclusively  in  the  market  for  that  item. 
The  economy  must  be  considered  as  a  synthesis  and  not  as  a  series  of 
unrelated  compartments. 

A  consideration  of  the  effect  of  price  changes  "during  the  downswing 
on  output  and  employment  in  the  whole  economy  must,  finally,  take 
account  of  the  relation  of  these  price  changes  to  changes  in  the  volume 
of  income  and  spending.     It  is  sometimes  assumed  m  the  discussion 

•0  Simon  Kuenets,  National  Income  and  Capital  Formation,  1919-36,  National  Bureaa  of  Economic 
Research,  p.  86. 

"  Financing  is  the  only  sector  of  construction  in  which  costs  have  been  effectively  reduced  during 
recent  years,  oy  such  programs  as  the  Federal  Housing  Act. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  43 

of  price  and  production  relationships  that  the  volmne  of  income  and 
spending  is  independent  of  price  changes.  It  follows  on  this  assump- 
tion that  any  reduction  in  prices  will  lead-to  an  mcrease  in  output  and 
probably  of  employment.  But  prices  not  only  represent  the  cost  of 
acquiring  commodities'  to  those  with  incomes  to  spend;  they  also 
determine  m  part  the  incomes  of  those  who  have  commodities  or 
services  to  sell.  A  reduction  in  prices  may  lead  *o  such  a  reduction 
in  spending  as  to  leave  the  volume  of  output  and  employment  and 
the  national  income  in  the  whole  economy  substantially  unchanged. 
Here  again  the  relationship  is  mutual ;  changes  in  the  rate  of  spending 
will  have  material  effects  upon  prices. 

The  crux  of  the  problem  seems  to  be  the  relation  of  price  changes 
to  spending  and  investment.  Although  this  relaJ^ion  has  not  been 
fully  studied,  it  appears  that  in  some  fields  at  least,  pu^  ticularly  in  the 
case  of  durable  goods,  properly  timed  and  coordinated  price  reduc- 
tions during  periods  of  downturn  would  be  desirable  from  the  point 
of  view  of  the  general  economy.  For  example,  lower  prices  for  rail- 
road equipment  might  lead  to  replacement  and  modernization  pro- 
grams ;  and  simultaneous  reductions  in  the  various  prices  determining 
the  cost  of  construction  might  lead  to  an  earlier  recovery  of  invest- 
ment in  housing.  It  is  no  doubt  true  that  reductions  in  the  prices 
of  construction  materials  would  permit  a  public-spending  program  to 
make  a  greater  contribution  to  output  and  employment,  or  alter- 
natively to  make  the  same  contribution  with  a  smaller  budgetary 
deficit.  Consequently,  governmental  efforts  to  reduce  prices  of 
strategic  commodities,  and  of  such  noncommodity  items  as  financing 
costs,  might  be  rewarded  by  an  appreciable  net  stimulus  to  production 
and  employment. 

PRICE    RELATIONSHIPS 

In  the  preceding  section  the  effect  of  price  behavior  upon  production 
was  considered  in  the  light  of  the  experience  of  individual  industries 
or  groups  of  industries,  though  the  interrelated  character  of  the 
economy  was  stressed.  In  addition  it  may  be  helpful  to  approach 
the  problem  from  another  point  of  view,  by  looking  at  the  relation- 
ships existing  among  commodity  prices  generally. 

During  periods  of  violent  price  movement,  differences  in  the  be- 
havior of  individual  prices  necessarily  result  in  marked  changes  in  the 
relationship  of  prices  to  each  other.  This  alters  the  exchange  patterns 
existing  between  the  different  segments  of  the  economy,  as  weU  as  the 
cost-price  structures  of  individual  industries.  Changes  in  these  rela- 
tionships maj'-,  in  turn,  be  expected  to  exert  an  important  influence 
upon  the  demand  for  the  products  of  specific  industries,  as  well  as 
upon  the  general  rate  of  business  activity  and  upon  employment. 

It  is  evident  from  an  examination  of  chart  VI  that  the  behavior 
of  prices  is  closely  related  to  the  rate  of  business  activity.  Tliis 
chart  shows  three  curves.  One  is  the  Federal  Reserve  Board  Index 
of  Industrial  Production,  which  is  a  general  indicator  of  the  level  of 
business  activity.  The  second  shows  the  movement  of  the  average 
of  30  basic  sensitive  commodity  prices.  The  third  is  a  measure  of  the 
way  in  which  commodity  prices  diverge  from  their  predepression  rela- 
tions to  each  other,  as  explained  in  more  detail  below.  (See  pp.  45-47.) 
Thus  a  decline  in  this  index  of  price  relationships  registers  a  departure 


44 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


o 

h- 
o 

o 
o 
q: 

Q. 

< 

a: 

I- 
co 

3 
Z 

cn 

o 
o 


o 
o 

o 
< 

CD 

>- 
I- 

oc 

X 


UJ 
O 

a: 

Q. 
UJ 

< 

CO 
UJ 

_J 
o 

I 


i!2 


o 

(/) 
a: 
lij 

Q. 

en 
o 

iij 
o 

CL  9 


cn  - 

_J 
< 
o 
o 

q: 


o 

z 
< 


^^ 

r 

y 

=^^ 

4 

> 

f» 

\ 

I-   Z    - 

o 

c; 

"^•^ 

^< 

^^^^_|  v^ 

cr 

^^*^ 

a. 

Vt 

^^'''^^> 

o 

^ 

^^ 

i- 

["^N^i 

o 

1  ^^3*^»»^, 

3 

x,^^*  vVl          *v.^ 

O 

(^    1 

"^ 

o 
_  o:  _ 

Q. 

ie 

_/i 

\> 

•^ 

« 

•I 

? 

Ul 

L  o 

^ 

^ 

a. 

•«:: 

^ 

T" 

\ 

^ 
^ 

! 
1 

^ 

1 

1 
1 
1 

1 

.^  «•  i 


«32; 

o:   o  —  £ 
uj      "o  i_ 

Q   ••   O 

2  -  5i~ 
=  ^^; 

<n  £  "  e 
UJ    H   «    o 

O   "       £  = 
lO   e  UJ  ,  o 

?  gsi> 

en  z  ^  V 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  45 

from  the  pattern  of  prices  which  prevailed  during  1926,  while  a  rising 
index  denotes  an  approach  to  those  relationsliips. 

It  is  apparent  that  all  three  of  these  curves  are  generally  parallel. 
In  other  words,  when  industrial  production  declines  sharply,  the  level 
of  sensitive  commodity  prices  falls  and  there  is  an  ever-widening 
spread  among  wholesale  commodity  prices  generally  as  compared 
with  their  earlier  relationships.  An  increase  in  the  volume  of  pro- 
duction ie  associated  with  rising  sensitive  commodity  prices  and  with 
a  decreasing  spread  between  prices  in  wholesale  markets. 

It  is  far  more  difficult,  however,  to  interpret  the  m^eaning  of  these 
relationships  than  to  show  that  they  exist.  It  is  particularly  im- 
portant to  realize  that  wholesale  commodity  prices  are  only  one  part 
of  the  price  system.  The  relationships  between  wholesale  prices  and 
other  kinds  of  prices,  such  as  retail  prices  or  wages,  rents,  utility  rates, 
etc.,  may  be  fully  as  significant  for  the  functioning  of  the  economy  as 
the  relationships  between  different  groups  of  wholesale  prices. 

However,  it  will  simplify  the  analysis  first  to  concentrate  attention 
upon  wholesale  commodity  prices.  It  seems  axiomatic  that  certain 
price  relationships  are  more  conducive  than  others  to  the  full  function- 
ing of  our  economy.  Adverse  effects  may  therefore  be  anticipated 
when  there  are  any  drastic  distortions  from  such  relationships.  Un- 
fortunately, it  is  very  difficult  to  determine  just  what  set  of  relation- 
ships is  most  desirable.  If  it  be  assumed  that  the  pattern  which  pre- 
vailed between  1926  and  1929  was  more  conducive  to  full  resource 
utilization,  than  that  since  prevailing,  ^^  it  may  be  useful  to  examine 
the  departure  or  dispersion  from  the  former  pattern.  Aluch  analysis 
has  been  devoted  to  the  development  of  such  measures  of  price  dis- 
persion in  an  effort  to  relate  them  to  swings  in  general  business 
activity.  Frederick  C.  Mills  has  contributed  much  in  the  field,  and 
other  students  of  price  analysis  have  also  been  concerned  with  price 
dispersion. 

Recently  an  index  of  dispersion  has  been  developed  by  the  Works 
Progress  Administration.^^  This  is  based  upon  prices  of  the  45  com- 
modity subgroups  included  in  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  whole- 
sale index.  The  disparity  between  the  price  pattern  for  these 
subgroups  existing  at  any  time  and  that  which  prevailed  during  the  year 
1926,  is  first  computed.     (The  year  1926  is,  therefore,  the  assumed 

'2  It  may  well  be  that  some  of  the  price  relationships  existing  before  1929  contributed  to  the  subsequent 
downturn. 

"  Price  Dispersion  and  Industrial  Activity,  1928-1938.  Works  Progress  Administration;  February  1939. 
This  publication  also  describes  other  work  done  in  the  field:  "Frederick  C.  Mills  has  done  the  most  ex- 
tensive work  in  the  field  (a).  Among  others  who  have  investigated  this  aspect  of  price  analysis,  F.  Y. 
Edgeworth  utilized  as  the  measure  of  dispersion  the  so-called  modulus,  which  is  the  standard  deviation 
multiplied  by  the  square  root  of  2  (b).  Wesley  C.  Mitchell  made  effective  use  of  deciles  (c).  Dr.  Silver- 
stolpe  employed  the  mean  deviation  in  his  analysis  (d).  Irving  Fisher  has  used  the  standard  deviation 
computed  from  relative  prices  and  from  logarithms  of  relative  prices  (e).  Norman  Crump  originally  ex- 
perimented with  the  arithmetic  standard  deviation  and  the  logarithmic  deviation  (f).  His  most  practical 
compilations  utilized  the  arithmetic  coefficient  of  variation  and  a  measure  of  the  'angle  of  deviation  derived 
from  the  standard  deviation  and  the  arithmetic  mean.'  A.  h.  Bowley  has  made  use  of  the 'mean  percentage 
divergence,'  a  measure  similar  to.  the  mean  deviation  except  that  the  variations  which  are  averaged  are  the 
percentage  deviations  of  individual  relatives  from  their  geometric  mean  (g). 

"(a)  The  Behavior  of  Prices,  ch.  Ill,  see.  IV,  pp.  251-285. 

"(b)  Memoranda  in  Papers  Relating  to  Political  Economy  (I/ondon:  Macmillan  &  Co.,  1925),  vol.  I. 

"(c)  Business  Cvcles  (University  of  California  Press,  1913);  and  The  Making  and  Using  of  Index  Numbers 
(U.  S.  Department  of  Labor,  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  Bulletin  284,  1921),  pt.  I. 

"(d)  Dr.  Silverstolpe's  measures  have  been  published  in  the  Gotebergs  Handels  och  Sjofarts-Tidning. 

"''e)  The  Making  of  Index  Numbers,  A  Study  of  Their  Varieties,  Tests,  and  Reliability  (3d  ed.,  Boston: 
Houghton,  Mifflin  Co.,  1927). 

"(f)  The  Interrelation  and  Distribution  of  Prices  and  Their  Incidence  Upon  Price  Stabilization,  Journal 
of  the  Royal  Statistical  Society,  1924,  vol.  87,  pt.  II.  Mr.  Crump's  measures  of  dispersion  are  now  published 
currently  in  the  Financial  Times  of  London. 

"(g)  Relative  Changes'in  Price  and  Other  Index  Numbers,  Special  Memorandum,  No.  5  (London  and 
Cambridge  Economic  Se""ice,  February  1924." 


46 


CONCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


—  ii  o 

^   UJ 


o 

=> 
o 
o 
or 

Q. 

< 


UJ 


q: 


< 


o 

UJ 
X 

UJ 

o 


O  o 

si 


E- 

> 

A 

^ 

*•••* 

^ 

A 

E- 

"^-^ 

7 

-i 

E- 

^««i 

s 

.5" 

-E 

E- 

z 

? 

~^ 

7 

A 

E- 

q: 

UJ 

a. 
to 

UJ 

< 

> 

*•-, 

> 

-i 

^ 

a. 

>' 

z 
o 

O 

.    a.    - 

< 

-E 

-       « 

S. 

> 

;- 

.^> 

"7^ 

, 

4 

E- 

^ 
<. 

• 

> 

A 

^ 

"\ 

\ 

\ 

,    1 

•5 . 

•  s 

A 

E- 

^ 

^-' 

C 

y 

1 

f 

1 

iftii 
ill 

overage  deviation  in  1929 

The  production  indeies  on  the  1929  base  « 
computed  from  the   Federal  Reserve   Board  in 
(1923-1925-  100.0)    odjusted  for  seosono 
variotion. 

11  1  1  1  M  1  1  II  1  II  11  1  t  II  1,1  I  1  1  1  1  11  i  1  t, 

E- 

i 

i — 

1' 

■s 

1 

=- 

<> 

t-; 

£ 
1 

: 

)       i 

1 

1        ^ 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  47 

base.)  The  trend  of  this  disparity  or  deviation  is  expressed  in  terms 
of  index  numbers,  with  the  average  deviation  during  1929  being  taken 
as  100."  Chart  VII  depicts  the  behavior  of  this  index  for  the  period 
between  January  1928  and  July  193G,  and  shows  also  the  trend  of 
industrial  production  during  the  same  period.  The  relationship 
between  the  two  curves  is  striking.  In  general,  increases  in  price 
dispersion,  that  is,  a  widening  spread  of  prices,  seem  to  be  closely 
associated  with  decliaes  in  industrial  production,  while  reduction  in  the 
degree  of  dispersion  is  apparently  related  to  increases  in  productive 
activity.  However,  thiB  existence  of  this  close  relationship  does  not 
necessarily  imply  causaUty,  Distorted  price  relations  undoubtedly 
impede  business  activity  but  it  is  also  true  that  reduced  activity  tends 
to  disturb  price  relationships. 

Since  prices  differ  in  their  responsiveness  to  cyclical  influences,  it 
is  inevitable  that  price  patterns  during  boom  and  depression  should 
vary  markedly.  During  1932-33  flexible  prices  were,  by  definition, 
much  lower  with  respect  to  the  inflexible  than  had  been  true  in 
1928-29;  by  the  winter  of  1936-37  predepression  relationships  had 
been  approximately  reestablished;  during  the  subsequent  recession 
flexible  prices  again  tended  toward  lower  levels  while  the  inflexible 
remained  relatively  stable.  It  is  basically  these  shifts  which  the  dis- 
persion index  portrays. 

Partly  these  price  movements,  particularly  for  the  flexible  group, 
are  the  consequences  of  changes  in  the  level  of  business  activity. 

Partly  it  has  been  suggested,  these  shifting  relationships  are  also 
to  be  considered  causes  of  changes  in  business  level;  departure  from 
pre-depression  patterns  may  aggravate  recession  while  approach  to 
such  patterns  may  accelerate  recovery. 

There  have  been  many  efforts  to  explore  the  nature  of  this  inter- 
action and  much  has  been  written  about  the  manner  in  which  changing 
price  relationships  affect  productive  activity.  Many  lines  of  causa- 
tion have  been  suggested,  but  two  are  commonly  stressed. 

The  first  considers  the  exchange  mechanism  of  the  economy  as  a 
whole.  If,  at  any  given  time,  some  pattern  of  exchange  ratios  is 
conducive  to  the  full  utilization  of  productive  resources,  it  is  argued 
that  any  drastic  and  rapid  distortion  of  such  ratios  must  act  as  a 
depressant.  Especial  emphasis  has  been  placed  upon  what  is  undoubt- 
edly the  most  spectacular  of  these  distortions;  that  affecting  the  farmer. 
Between  1929  and  the  trough  of  the  depression,  the  ratio  between  the 
prices  of  the  commodities  which  the  farmer  had  to  sell  and  those  which 

"  This  index  and  its  derivation  are  thus  described  in  the  Works  Progress  Adm'nistration  publication  just 
referred  to: 

"The  measure  worked  out  in  the  course  of  the  present  investigation  is  calculated  by  weighting  the  varia- 
tions—which are  the  percentage  deviations  of  individual  relatives  from  their  weighted  mean — on  a  fixed 
base  (the  year  1926). 

"The  index  of  dispersion  ♦  •  •  is  simply  a  measure  of  the  spread  among  prices.  For  the  most  part, 
it  represents  the  spread  between  raw  materials  and  finished  goods  prices  •  •  •  although  the  calculation 
involves  the  prices  of  45  subgroups  of  commodilies.  The  direction  of  the  trend  indicates  whether  prices 
are  moving  toward  or  away  from  their  mean  (the  all-commodities  level). 

"The  computation  of  the  index  of  dispersion  involves,  first,  the  calculation  of  the  average  percentage 
deviation  which  is  the  amount  the  price  indexes  differed  from  the  m'ean  price  index  (a) .  In  this  method  ,the 
average  is  obtained  by  weighting  the  percentage  deviation  for  each  subgroup  by  its  value  of  production  in 
1935.  A  weighted  average  deviation  is  then  ^culated  for  each  month.  This  monthly  figure  is  divided 
by  the  1929  average  deviation  to  obtain  the  monthly  index  number  of  price  dispersion." 

(a)  The  subgroup  indexes  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  have  been  used  in  the  calculation  of  the 
average  deviation.  The  subgroup,  Structural  Steel,  was  omitted,  as  it  is  included  in  the  Iron  and  Steel 
subgroup. 


48  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

he  wanted  to  buy  declined  by  about  50  percent.  Other  things  being 
equal,  it  might  be  assumed  that  his  purchases  were  necessarily  cur- 
tailed by  about  the  same  percentage. 

So  far  the  argument  is  noncontroversial.  However,  the  effect  of 
such  a  contraction  in  the  purchasing  power  of  any  single  economic 
group  upon  the  economy  as  a  whole  is  very  complex.  Reduction  in 
the  price  of  farm  products  in  relation  to  other  prices  influences  the 
purchasing'  power  not  only  of  the  farmer  but  also  of  the  nonfarm 
population.  For  example,  if  as  a  result  of  such  a  change  in  price 
relationships,  the  cost  of  foods  and  clothing  to  the  industrial  worker 
falls  while  his  income  remains  the  same,  he  will  have  a  larger  sum 
available  for  expenditure  elsewhere.  There  are  two  sides  to  the 
equation. 

Nevertheless,  there  is  strong  reason  for  believing  that  the  net  result 
of  a  drastic  decline  in  farm  purchasing  power  upon  the  economy  is 
undesirable,  It  is  quite  likely  that  a  substantial  part  of  the  shift 
in  purchasing  power  accompanying  a  sharp  decline  in  farm  prices 
constitutes  a  shift  from  hands  which  would  spend  to  hands  which,  at 
least  in  part,  hoard.  It  is  not  at  all  certain  that  all  or  even  a  major 
part  of  the  reduction  in  farm  prices  would  be  passed  on  to  the  indus- 
trial worker  in  the  form  of  low  prices  for  the  necessities  of  life.  Much 
of  the  difference  might  be  absorbed  by  intermediate  groups  such  as 
manufacturers,  distributors,  and  banks.  Consequently  it  would  not 
be  rendered  available  for  the  immediate  purchase  of  consumable  goods 
in  quantities  sufficient  to  compensate  for  the  reduction  in  the  farmer's 
buying.  In  other  words,  the  importance  of  the  change  in  price  rela- 
tionships does  not  lie  so  much  in  the  relationships  themselves,  as  in 
the  shifts  in  purchasing  power  which  they  signify.  Any  sudden  drastic 
change  in  the  purchasing  power  of  an  important  economic  group  may 
be  expected  to  affect  the  economy  materially;  if  the  group  involved 
is  one  which  normally  spends  a  major  share  of  its  income  for  consump- 
tion goods  the  effect  is  likely  to  be  adverse. 

But,  this  is  only  one  part  of  the  stoiy.  In  view  of  the  stress  laid 
upon  the  influence  of  price  disparities  upon  the  farmer,  it  may  be  well 
to  examine  that  situation  more  fully.  Table  2  shows  that  the  dis- 
parity between  the  prices  of  farm  and  industrial  products  was  but  one 
of  the  exchange  problems  affecting  American  agriculture  during  the 
depression.  Prices  of  noncommodity  items,  such  as  mortgage  inter- 
est, farm  taxes,  freight  and  utility  rates  are  materially  less  sensitive 
to  cyclical  influences  than  even  industrial  commodity  prices,  yet  a 
substantial  share  of  the  farmer's  income  is  allocated  to  these  inflexible 
noncommodity  expenditures. 


A 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


49 


Table  2. — Selected  indexes  of  prices,  wages,  costs  of  distribution,  farm  taxes,  and 

mortgage  interest,  191S-S8 

[1910-14=100] 


Year 


a)  2 


Prices  paid  by 
farmers  for  com- 
modities used 
for— 


"5 
a  o  g 
t;  '-'.2 


^       o. 


•O 

OS 

S 

<S 

B 

£ 

0) 

2 

at 

a 
S 

Q< 

3 

'1 

a 

a 

1 

s 

§ 

a 

IS 

o 

s 
a 

OS 

a 

E 

¥ 

S9 

;^ 

f^ 

05 

O 

fR 

103 

103 

100 

98 

104 

111 

101 

104 

100 

99 

105 

113 

103 

105 

100 

99 

105 

122 

113 

112 

100 

97 

110 

129 

141 

127 

101 

98 

129 

143 

177 

157 

115 

116 

159 

152 

207 

184 

129 

133 

174 

191 

242 

223 

147 

144 

202 

232 

155 

205 

164 

174 

190 

248 

151 

198 

IfS 

160 

175 

249 

169 

212 

153 

152 

177 

253 

173 

220 

153 

152 

180 

253 

176 

221 

152 

150 

185 

258 

179 

225 

152 

147 

192 

258 

179 

228 

152 

147 

190 

264 

179 

230 

151 

147 

190 

266 

180 

232 

150 

146 

198 

26S 

167 

232 

149 

144 

196 

264 

130 

222 

146 

143 

178 

241 

96 

197 

145 

142 

153 

209 

85 

192 

147 

136 

140 

179 

95 

213 

145 

133 

158 

170 

103 

221 

142 

134 

174 

172 

111 

224 

138 

132 

171 

173 

126 

243 

139 

127 

180 

179 

124 

247 

144 

134 

173 

W 

.a^^ 


1913.. 
1914.. 
1915.. 
1916.. 
1917.. 
1918.. 
1919.- 
1920.. 
1921.. 
1922.. 
1923.. 
1924.. 
1925.. 
1926.. 
1927.. 
1928.. 
1929.. 
1930.. 
1931.. 
1932.. 
1933.. 
1934.. 
1935.. 
1936. . 

1937  . 

1938  ». 


101 
101 
38 
118 
175 
202 
213 
211 
125 
132 
142 
143 
156 
145 
139 
149 
146 
126 
87 
65 
70 
90 
108 
114 
121 
95 


100 
102 
107 
124 
147 
177 
210 
222 
161 
156 
160 
159 
164 
162 
159 
160 
158 
148 
126 
108 
109 
122 
124 
122 
128 
122 


102 

99 
104 
124 
151 
174 
192 
174 
141 
139 
141 
143 
147 
146 
145 
148 
147 
140 
122 
107 
108 
125 
126 
126 
135 
124 


101 
100 
105 
124 
149 
176 
202 
201 
152 
140 
152 
152 
157 
155 
153 
155 
153 
145 
124 
107 
109 
123 
125 
124 
130 
122 


103 
107 
114 
125 
143 
166 
196 
221 
226 
234 
233 
236 
238 
235 
232 
227 
221 
214 
205 
195 
167 
149 
147 
144 
140 
(«) 


>  Index  of  comRpsite  wages  in  the  United  States,  Federal  Reserve  Bank  of  New  York.    Converted  from 
1926  base. 
1  Average  of  indexes  of  freight  rates  on  wheat,  livestock,  and  cotton,  1913=100. 
5  Prior  to  1916,  year  beginning  July  1,  Interstate  Commerce  Commission. 

*  Farm  Economics,  Cornell  Agricultural  College. 

•  Preliminary. 

« Data  not  available. 


Source:  Bureau  of  Agricultural  Economics, 
tural  Marketing  Service. 


Farm  wage  rates  and  freight  rates  compiled  by  the  Agrlcul- 


During  1932,  for  example,  the  price  of  farm  products  had  declined 
about  55  percent  from  their  1929  level,  while  mortgage  interest  pay- 
able had  been  reduced  by  only  12  percent.  The  amount  which  must 
be  paid  in  any  year  on  long-term  debts  does  not  vary  with  changes 
in  the  prevailing  rate  of  interest  from  year  to  year.  It  alters  only  as 
debts  mature  and  are  refunded,  as  creditors  make  voluntary  adjust- 
ments to  meet  changing  conditions,  or  as  statutes  are  enacted  to 
relieve  acute  distress. 

Consequently  an  increase  in  price  flexibility  for  commodities  bought 
by  the  farmer  (e.  g.,  fertilizer,  agricultural  machinery),  could  con- 
tribute only  in  a  limited  way  to  the  solution  of  the  farmer's  purchasing 
problem.  The  benefit  which  he  mjght  derive  from  reductions  in  the 
prices  of  manufactured  goods  is  limited  by  the  fraction  of  his  income 
which  remains  after  essential  expenditures  for  noncommodity  items 
have  been  met. 

Moreover,  it  should  be  remembered  that  the  farmer  makes  most  of 
his  purchases  not  on  the  wholesale  but  on  the  retail  markets.  The 
preceding  discussion  is  centered  about  the  behavior  of  wholesale  prices 


50  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

largely  because  the  body  of  wholesale  price  data  available  is  much 
more  comprehensive  than  that  for  retail  prices.  Yet  a  very  substan- 
tial fraction,  probably  approximating  40  percent,  of  total  consumer 
expenditures  for  commodities  represents  the  mark-up  of  various  whole- 
sale and  retail  distributors  added  to  the  manufacturer's  wholesale 
price.  In  general,  also,  retail  prices  are  somewhat  less  flexible  than 
wholesale  prices  for  the  same  commodities.  It  appears  that  in  dis- 
cussions of  the  consequences  of  price  rigidity  too  much  stress  has  been 
laid  upon  the  behavior  of  wholesale  prices  and  insufficient  attention 
has  been  devoted  to  the  inflexibility  of  retail  prices  and  distributive 
margins.  ^ 

As  far  as  the  farmer  is  concerned,  the  most  serious  consequences 
of  commodity  price  rigidity  flow  from  the  behavior  of  those  items 
which  are  either  essential  for  production  of  his  crops  or  are  necessities 
of  life  for  his  family.  Thus,  the  cotton  or  tobacco  farmer  would  benefit 
very  materially  if  the  behavior  of  the  price  of  fertilizer  were  more 
closely  parallel  to  the  price  fluctuations  of  what  he  has  to  sell.  On 
the  other  hand,  the  existence  of  relatively  insensitive  prices  for  com- 
modities which  constitute  marginal  or  postponable  expenditures  af- 
fects him  far  less  severely. 

Although  the  immediately  preceding  discussion  has  focused  upon 
the  plight  of  the  farmer,  essentially  similar  considerations  apply  to 
consumers  generally.  The  impact  of  changes  in  exchange  relation- 
ships upon  various  segments  of  the  economy  is,  therefore,  selective. 
Some  commodity  price  rigidities  may  result  in  such  shifts  of  purchasing 
power  as  to  create  serious  impediments  to  the  normal  flow  of  exchange 
during  periods  of  depressed  business  activity.  In  the  case  of  others, 
the  detriment  to  one  group  may  be  roughly  balanced  by  the  benefit 
to  another,  so  that  the  net  effect  upon  the  economy  as  a  whole  is 
small. 

Cost-price  relationships. — Essentially  similar  considerations  apply 
to  the  second  aspect  of  price  unbalance  which  has  received  major 
attention — the  disturbance  of  cost-price  relationships  industry  by 
industry.  It  may  be  desirable  to  achieve  a  substantial  degree  of 
covariation  between  the  price  of  any  product  and  the  cost  of  its  pro- 
duction, particularly  between  the  prices  of  finished  goods  and  the  costs 
of  their  raw  materials.  Assuming  this  to  be  so,  noncommodity  ex- 
penditures again  constitute  a  basic  limiting  factor.  Overhead  costs 
per  unit  rise  rather  than  decline  as  sales  fall  and  production  is  cur- 
tailed. Were  it  conceivable  that  all  administered  prices  behaved 
precisely  as  if  they  were  market  dominated,  distortions  would  still 
remain  between  commodity  prices  and  noncommodity  prices.  In 
some  cases,  at  least,  they  might  even  become  more  serious. 

Consequently  in  appraising  the  effect  of  disturbed  price  relation- 
ships upon  business  activity  and  production,  it  cannot  be  too  strongly 
emphasized  that  the  problem  goes  far  beyond  the  behavior  of  whole- 
sale commodity  prices.  Referring  back  to  chart  VI,  it  is  apparent 
that  the  trend  of  industrial  production  is  associated  just  about  as 
closely  with  the  behavior  of  sensitive  commodity  prices  as  it  is  with 
the  index  of  dispersion  which  measures  commodity  price  disparities. 
It  may  even  be  possible  that  the  violent  movement  of  the  sensitive 
price  group  in  relation  to  the  pattern  of  fixed  costs  may  affect  the 
economy  as  seriously  as  the  failure  of  inflexible  commodity  prices  to 
parallel  the  movement  of  the  flexible. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  51 

CONCLUSIONS 

It  has  been  shown  that,  within  very  broad  limits,  there  was  a 
tendency  for  production  to  fall  less  where  prices  fell  more  during 
the  1929-33  recession.  Conversely,  where  prices  were  maintained 
production  fell  much  more  sharply.  It  has  been  emphasized  that  there 
were  very  many  exceptions  to  this  generalization.  It  has  been 
pointed  out  moreover  that  the  existence  of  this  limited  correlation 
does  not  of  itself  imply  any  causal  relationship. 

For  any  individual  commodity,  price  is  but  one,  and  not  necessarily 
the  most  important,  of  the  factors  which  affect  its  production.  Thus 
the  relatively  sharp  decline  in  the  consumption  of  most  durable  goods 
between  1929  and  1933  was  probably  aggravated  by  the  stability  of 
their  prices,  but  it  seems  likely  that  the  postponable  nature  of  their 
demand  in  combination  with  lower  family  incomes  was  of  at  least  equal 
or  of  greater  importance.  With  the  spread  of  unemployment  and  a 
marked  curtailment  of  purchasing  power,  the  sale  of  goods  whose 
purchase  is  relatively  more  postponable  will  usually  decline  regardless 
of  price ;  the  sale  of  articles  designed  to  satisfy  wants  which  cannot  be 
long  deferred  is  likely  to  be  fairly  well  maintained,  again  regardless 
of  price. 

Moreover  assuming  any  specific  set  of  market  conditions,  or  any 
given  level  of  purchasing  power,  the  effect  of  a  change  in  the  price  of 
any  commodity  upon  the  purchases  of  that  commodity  may  be  slight. 
This  is  tantamount  to  saying  that  demand  for  many  products,  particu- 
larly during  periods  of  depressed  business  activity,  varies  little  regard- 
less of  price.  Among  the  most  notable  examples  of  such  "inelastic 
demand"  are  products  such  as  steel  castings,  which  find  no  independent 
market  but  whose  demand  is  part  of  a  joint  demand  for  some  more 
complex  finished  goods  of  whose  total  cost  they  constitute  but  a  small 
part.-  In  cases  of  tliis  sort,  isolated  changes  in  price  may  have  no 
discernible  effect  upon  consumption  whatever.  Nor  can  isolated  price 
changes  during  periods  of  curtailed  purchasing  power  expect  to  influ- 
ence materially  the  sales  of  such  products  as  absolute  necessities  of 
life  or  capital  equipment  for  industries  operating  at  fractions  of  their 
capacity. 

However,  the  price  behavior  of  any  single  commodity  has  implica- 
tions ^ar  broader  than  merely  its  relation  to  the  production  of  that 
commodity.  Assuming  the  extreme  case  of  an  article  whose  demand  is 
absolutely  inelastic,  a  change  in  its  price  may  importantly  affect  the 
amount  available  for  expenditure  elsewhwere.  Or,  taking  a  typical 
case  of  joint  demand,  a  reduction  in  the  price  of  bricks  alone  may  have 
little  effect  upon  the  consumption  of  bricks  themselves,  but  if  coupled 
with  similar  reductions  in  the  prices  of  other  building  materials,  its 
influence  might  be  far  reacliing.  Similarly,  a  simultaneous  cut  in  the 
price  of  electric  appliances,  electric  power  rates,  and  installation  costs 
would  probably  have  a  very  different  effect  on  sales  of  electric  equip- 
ment, even  during  a  downturn,  than  woidd  a  reduction  in  equipment 
prices  alone. 

In  other  words,  if  the  demand  curve  for  a  specific  product  is  in- 
elastic, a  change  in  its  price  taken  alone  may  have  very  Uttle  direct 
effect  upon  its  consumption,  yet  it  may  cause  an  appreciable  shift  in 
the  position  of  the  demand  curves  for  other  commodities.  The  cumu- 
lative effect  of  many  such  changes  may  be  very  considerable.     Con- 


52  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

sequeixtly,  in  considering  the  implications  of  the  disparate  behavior 
of  the  prices  of  different  commodities  during  downturn,  it  is  essential 
that  attention  be  directed  upon  the  economy  as  a  whole  and  not  upon 
isolated  segments  of  it  taken  separately.  Moreover,  it  has  been  shown 
that  LQ  appraising  the  effects  of  different  kinds  of  price  behavior  and 
in  striving  to  form  a  judgment  as  to  those  best  suited  to  promote 
recovery,  it  is  necessary  to  consider  not  only  commodity  prices  but 
also  the  behavior  of  the  prices  of  many  other  items,  such  as  wages, 
interest,  rent,  etc. 

Some  attention  has  been  devoted  to  the  considerations  which  in- 
fluence busLuess  firms  in  their  decisions  as  to  price  policy.  The 
horizon  of  each  firm  is  necessarily  limited.  In  framing  policy  it  con- 
siders primarily  the  effect  of  its  decisions  upon  its  own  profit  and 
loss  account.  It  would  be  unrealistic  to  expect  any  individual  business 
to  reduce  its  prices  materially  in  the  face  of  its  belief — whether  or 
not  warranted — that  such  reduction  would  not  be  compensated  for  by 
an  increase  in  sales.  For  example,  the  producer  of  a  commodity 
subject  to  joint  demand  will  not  in  the  ordinary  course  of  things  reduce 
his  prices  any  more  than  he  must,  unless  he  has  some  reasonable 
ground  for  expecting  that  the  producers  of  related  items  entering  into 
the  same  finished  article  wUl  do  so  simultaneously. 

But  although  a  broader  view  probably  transcends  the  immediate 
horizon  of  the  individual  firm,  it  does  not  exceed  the  scope  of  public 
policy.  It  may  be  precisely  in  this  field,  too,  that  governmental 
action  can  be  most  profitably  directed.  In  such  a  key  sector  of  indus- 
try as  building  construction,  for  example,  there  is  opportunity  for 
a  concerted  approach.  If  means  could  be  secured  for  simultaneous 
price  reductions  among  all  producers  of  important  building  materials, 
by  labor,  and  by  finftncial  agencies  to  reduce  the  cost  of  financing,  it 
might  supply  the  incentive  which  is  now  lacking;  insuring  to  each 
group  that  its  own  change  of  policy  will  be  paralleled  by  such  other 
changes  as  would  in  the  aggregate  exert  an  appreciable  effect  upon 
the  market. 

The  technique  by  which  such  a  program  could  be  effectuated  is 
beyond  the  scope  of  the  present  discussion.  Certainly,  however,  the 
interrelated  character  of  the  problem  makes  necessary  some  such 
interrelated  approach.  Attention  would  first  have  to  be  directed  to 
determining  those  broad  fields  in  which  such  efforts  could  be  most 
profitably  expended. 

Finally,  it  is  evident  that  concern  with  wholesale  commodity  prices 
should  not  exclude  consideration  of  retail  markets.  It  has  been 
pointed  out  that  retail  prices  are,  in  general,  less  flexible  than  wholesale 
prices.  If  it  be  considered  desirable  that  prices  of  certain  commodities 
be  reduced  during  periods  of  depressed  business  activity,  it  would 
seem  at  least  equally  important  that  such  reductions  extend  to  retail 
as  well  as  wholesale  markets.  It  is  likely  that  some  of  the  recent 
activities  of  Government  are  operating  in  the  reverse  direction.  Thus, 
resale  price  maintenance  legislation — the  so-called  "Fair  Trade  Acts," 
together  with  the  Federal  Miller-Tydings  Enabling  Act— have 
increased  the  rigidity  of  the  prices  of  many  trade-marked  commodities. 
It  is  possible  that  the  state  "Unfair  Practices  Acts"  and  the  Robinson- 
Patman  Act  have  reduced  the  flexibility  of  distributive  margins  in 
certain   markets.     It   may   be  well,   therefore,   for   Government   to 


\ 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  53 

reexamine  its  policy  with  regard  to  laws  affecting  the  system  of  dis- 
tribution in  the  light  of  these  considerations. 

All  these  suggestions  obviously  fail  to  go  to  the  heart  of  the  problem. 
They  represent  merely  isolated  approaches  on  a  few  scattered  fronts. 
Despite  the  intensive  analysis  to  which  price  inflexibility  has  been 
subjected  during  the  past  few  years,  no  adequate  proposals  for  any 
more  comprehensive  approach  have  emerged.  There  is  little  doubt 
that  the  behavior  of  prices  intimately  affects  the  rate  of  business 
activity.  Nevertheless  it  seems  equally  evident  that  no  simple,  single 
approach  to  prices  as  such  will  solve  the  problem  of  increasing  and 
maintaining  industrial  activity.     The  problem  is  far  too  complex. 


CHAPTER  III » 
NONPRICE  COMPETITION 

SUMMARY 

Price- is  but  one  of  the  avenues— and  not  necessarily  the  most 
significant — through  which  competition  expresses  itself.  It  has  been 
pointed  out  in  chapter  I  that  there  are  himdreds  of  other  grounds 
upon  which  sellers  may  choose  to  compete,  such  as  the  offer  of  better 
quality,  more  elaborate  service,  more  attractive  guarantees,  more 
convenient  terms  of  payment,  chromium  plating,  neon  lights,  cello- 
phane wrappings,  better  radio  programs,  etc.  Reference  has  been 
made  to  the  probability  that  the  relative  importance  of  all  these 
latter  devices  for  winning  business,  which  may  be  collectively  desig- 
nated "nonprice  competition,"  has  increased  materially  during  the 
past  generation,  while  the  emphasis  on  the  price  aspects  of  compe- 
tition has  correspondingly  declined. 

This  change  in  competitive  emphasis  has  many  implications.  In 
the  first  place  it  inevitably  alters  the  focus  of  government  policy 
(Resigned  to  cope  with  the  problems  of  monopoly  and  competition  in 
industrial  markets.  The  efficacy  of  any  program  based  upon  or 
directed  toward  the  behavior  of  prices  alone  neglects  elements  of 
vital  importance.     ' 

More  broadly  the  direction  which  competitive  rivalry  takes  in- 
fluences in  many  important  ways  the  amount  and  variety  of  goods 
which  are  produced  for  consumption  and  the  standard  of  living  of 
consumers  generally.  The  efl'ect  upon  the  well-being  of  the  ultimate 
consumer  is  especially  marked  because  many  forms  of  non price 
competition  are  particularly  significant  in  relation  to  retail  markets 
•  and  to  the  everyday  necessities  of  life. 

The  analysis  presented  in  this  chapter  is  in  no  sense  a  complete 
survey  of  all  forms  of  nonprice  competition;  it  is  confined  to  a  few 
of  the  more  significant.  Nevertheless,  it  suffices  to  elicit  the  extreme 
complexity  of  the  issues  involved. 

Nonprice  competition  expresses  itself  through  a  wide  variety  of 
avenues.  Perhaps  the  most  important  of  these  is  the  actual  quality 
or  content  of  the  products  involved.  For  example,  little  effort  has 
been  made  during  recent  years  to  reduce  the  price  of  automobiles  to 
the  consumer.  Instead,  stress  has  been  placed  upon  constant  im- 
provement in  quality,  performance,  and  appearance.  Automobile 
advertising  reflects  this  policy,  placing  little  emphasis  upon  price 
and  much  ^  upon  distinctive  mechanical  features,  economy,  and 
beauty  of  line.  The  same  observation  applies  to  a  greater  or  less 
extent  to  most  other  complex  mechanisms  such  as  radios,  refrigerators, 

'  Ch.  Ill  was  prepared  by  Saul  Nelson.  Laura  Mae  Brown  compiled  the  bulk  of  the  material  upon 
which  the  analysis  is  based,  particularly  with  reference  to  the  influence  of  business  convention  as  exempli- 
fied by  the  institution  of  price  lines. 

54 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  55 

oil  burners,  vacuum  cleaners,  and  the  like.^  In  the  case  of  refrig- 
erators, for  example,,  the  retail  prices  of  comparable  models  of 
competing  makes  are  identical  almost  to  the  penny. 

Differences  between  rival  products  may  represent  very-  real  cor- 
responding differences  of  desirability  or  usefulness.  In  addition, 
however,  there  is  an  undoubted  tendency  to  create  the  appearance  of 
difference  where  no  real  intrinsic  difference  in  physical  utility  exists. 
In  developing  and  retaining  a  market,  producers  and  distributors 
make  strenuous  efforts  to  distinguish  their  products  in  the  public 
eye  from  those  sold  by  their  competitors.  As  a  result,  competition 
in  quality  often  takes  the  form  of  adding  minor  eye-catching  features 
bearing,  at  best,  a  remote  relationship  to  the  intrinsic  utility  of  the 
product.  Intensive  advertising  campaigns,  describing  the  merits  of 
such  features,  are  frequently  accepted  by  the  public  with  somewhat 
more  credence  than  their  accuracy  warrants.'  Buyers  may  come  to 
demand  them  with  little  or  no  regard  for  price  relationships  and  to 
reject,  as  inferior,  products  not  bearing  them. 

Although  nonprice  competition  is  most  commonly  associated  with 
the  element  of  quality,  it  should  not  be  concluded  that  this  is  its  only 
aspect.  Collateral  terms  of  sale  are  often  important.  Among  these 
are  guarantees  of  service  or  performance.  In  the  case  of  rubber  tires, 
for  example,  guarantees  of  mileage,  backed  by  appropriate  provisions 
for  allowance  in  case  the  product  falls  short  of  the  guaranteed  per- 
formance, probably  exert  a  distinct  influence  upon  the  market.  The 
provision  of  adequate  facilities  for  service  and  replacement  has  received 
much  attention  in  certain  lines  of  business.  Thus,  an  automobile 
purchaser  must  consider  not  only  its  first  cost,  but  also  the  prices 
which  he  will  be  called  upon  to  pay  for  inevitable  rej!)airs.  The  sale 
of  one  line  of  agricultural  implements  has  been  distinctly  handicapped 
by  the  lack  of  an  adequate  widespread  service  organization. 

The  direction  which  competitive  rivalry  takes  in  any  given  industry 
is  influenced  both  by  the  intrinsic  nature  of  its  markets  and  by  policy 
decisions  of  the  concerns  comprising  it.  In  some  industries,  for  ex- 
ample, the  nature  of  the  product  is  such  that  elements  of  quality  and 
style  inevitably  exercise  an  important  influence  upon  the  buyer's  selec- 
tion. This  is  true,  for  example,  in  the  apparel  markets  in  which  well- 
defined  "price  lines"  have  become  recognized  as  the  result  of  custom 
and  convenience.  Thus,  there  is  a  limited  number  of  wholesale  prices 
at  which  almost  all  women's  medium-price  dresses  are  sold  These 
wholesale  prices  are,  in  turn,  reflected  in  similar,  though  somewhat 
less  rigid,  lines  in  retail  markets.  As  a  result  the  focus  of  competition 
becomes  the  character  of  the  garments  which  can  be  offered  at  the 
accepted  price  and  not  the  price  at  which  some  specific  garment  should 
be  quoted. 

In  their  decision  to  stress  nonprice  elements  in  sales  strategy,  busi- 
ness concerns  are  often  influenced  by  the  desire  to  avoid  direct  price 
competition  with  their  rivals.  This  has  been  one  of  the  major  factors 
in  stimulating  the  use  of  advertising  and  of  distinguishing  brands  and 
trade-marks.  Much  effort  has  been  devoted  to  persuading  the  pros- 
pective buyer  that  advertised  and  branded  products  have  qualities 
which  distinguish  them  in  important  ways  from  similar  products  sold 

2  In  such  lines  as  radios  and  refrifjerators,  whose  growth  has  been  fairly  recent,  prices  have  been  materially 
reduced  as  techniques  of  production  improved.  However,  even  In  these  cases  sales  emphasis  at  any  given 
time  usually  centers  upon  features  other  than  price. 

U47149— 41— No.  1 G 


56  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

by  others.  These  efforts  have  been  most  successful  in  those  fields  in 
which  consumers  find  it  particularly  difficult  to  form  objective  judg- 
ments of  the  quality  and  usefulness  of  the  merchandise.  The  drug 
and  cosmetic  industry  furnishes  an  outstanding  example  of  the  manner 
in  which  the  effective  use  of  these  techniques  can  shield  trade-marked 
products  from  direct  price  competition  with  similar  merchandise;  very 
wide  price  spreads  exist  between  virtually  identical  products  differing 
only  in  name. 

Business  policy  decisions  to  stress  some  form  of  nonprice  competi- 
tion may  represent  a  voluntary  choice.  However,  concerns  which 
prefer  to  compete  on  a  price  basis  are  sometimes  forced  to  adopt  what 
they  consider  a  less  satisfactory  alternative  because  of  pressure  applied 
from  without.  Such  pressure  may  result  from  Government  regula- 
tion of  price  or  perhaps  from  coercion  by  competitors. 

In  general,  businessmen  have  displayed  much  ingenuity  in  seeking 
some  competitive  outlet  as  alternative  to  price  reductions.  Under-^ 
N.  R.  A.,  when  many  prices  were  controlled  by  code  provisions,  some 
of  the  schemes  adopted  verged  on  the  fantastic.  For  example,  a  retail 
druggist  in  California,  unable  to  cut  prices,  employed  a  medium  to 
give  free  psychic  readings  to  his  customers.  An  automobile  dealer  was 
accused  of  indirect  price  cutting  because  he  bought  six  suits  of  .clothes 
from  a  tailor  to  whom  he  sold  a  car.  Lumber  manufacturers  cut 
prices  indirectly  by  shipping  a  higher  quality  of  lumber  than  the  in- 
voice called  for.  Coal  producers  offered  guarantees  of  heat  content 
which  they  knew  were  impossible  of  fulfillment,  backed  by  a  penalty 
in  case  the  fuel  failed  to  meet  the  standards  set.  Price-maintenance 
laws  (the  "Fair  Trade"  Acts)  which  largely  eliminate  price  competi- 
tion between  retailers  selling  trade-marked  products  have  resulted  in 
emphasis  upon  elaborate  service  in  some  cases,  and  in  a  search  for 
indirect  ways  of  granting  price  concessions  in  others. 

In  some  irrdustries,  although  legal  controls  may  be  absent,  the  fear 
that  price  reductions  may  lead  to  price  wars  often  results  in  the 
multiplication  of  grades  and  sizes.  For  example,  instead  of  cutting 
prices  on  a  standard  grade  of  fertilizer,  the  producer  may  introduce 
'a  slightly  different  grade.  As  competitors  match  the  new  mix,  the 
process  is  repeated.  In  many  states  the  number  of  different  grades 
became  so  bewildering  that  laws  were  passed  to  limit  the  variety  that 
could  be  sold.  Similar  practices  have  occurred  in  many  other 
industries. 

This  very  cursory  review  of  some  phases  of  nonprice  competition 
emphasizes  both  the  importance  of  the  issues  and  the  difficulties  of 
any  unqualified  appraisal.  It  seems  reasonably  clear  that  the  change 
in  competitive  emphasis  has  not  been  entirely  undesirable.  Thus  it 
is  probably  true  that  the  increased  attention  paid  to  quality  and  per- 
formance has  served  to  stimulate  technical  research.  Certainly  the 
automobile,  the  refrigerator,  and  the  tractor  are  more  satisfactory 
products  today  than  they  were  some  years  ago.  Undoubtedly 
technical  advances  would  have  occurred  even  if  competition  had 
focused  upon  price,  but  it  is  at  least  arguable  that  centering  attention 
upon  quality  served  as  a  more  effective  stimulation  to  its  improve- 
ment than  would  otherwise  have  been  possible.  Conversely,  there 
is  some  evidence  that  excessive  emphasis  upon-  price  may  lead  at 
times  to  undesirable  degradation  of  quality. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  57 

Where  products  are  highly  diversified  and  comparability  between 
rival  merchandise  is  very  difficult  to  obtain,  the  elimination  of  price 
as  a  major  competitive  factor  may  actually  simplify  the  consumer's 
problems  of  selection.  For  example,  since  the  standardization  of 
women's  dresses  is  remote  from  reality,  the  institution  of  price  lines 
is  not  without  benefit.  It  is  probably  simpler  for  the  average  con- 
sumer to  select  the  dress  she  likes  best  at  a  given  price  than  to  weigh 
the  desirability  of  small  differences  in  price  as  against  small  differences 
in  quahty. 

On  the  other  hand  it  must,  be  recognized  that  emphasis  upon 
quality  has  often  served  to  divert  effort  from  programs  designed  to 
produce  cheap  but  satisfactory  merchandise  to  meet  the  needs  of 
lower-income  groups.  It  has  been  argued,  for  example,  that  the 
production  of  cheaper  automobiles  or  refrigerators,  stripped  of  all 
luxury  features,  could  serve  a  useful  purpose  in  expanding  the  poten- 
tial market  for  those  products. 

One  of  the  most  serious  objections  to  many  forms  of  nonprice. 
competition  is  the  manner  in  which  they  complicate  the  buyer's 
problems  of  selection.  Price  is  a  universal  measure  and  the  signifi- 
cance of  a  price  difference  is  readily  understood  by  any  buyer.  The 
appraisal  of  differences  in  content  or  quality,  or  the  translation  of 
collateral  terms  of  sale  into  price  equivalents,  is  much  more  difficult, 
particularly  for  the  average  untrained  consumer.  Consequently, 
when  the  policy  of  distinguishing  one's  product  from  a  competitor's 
is  revealed  not  in  any  real  betterment  of  quality  but  in  the  multiplica- 
tion of  unneeded  gadgets  and  superficial  eye-catching  features,  there 
may  be  a  distinct  loss  of  competitive  efficiency.  It  is  unlikely  that 
fancy  packaging  is  of  as  much  value  to  the  consumer  as  low  prices  or 
improved  quality.  The  forms  taken  by  nonprice  competition  when 
it  reflects  the  suppression  of  price  competition  through  collusive  or 
coercive  tactics  seem  particularly  valueless  in  serving  the  economic 
system.  All  these  schemes  have  the  disadvantage  of  substituting  for 
a  direct  price  cut,  which  the  consumer  wants  and  can  measure,  some 
substitute  of  uncertain  value  which  he  can  well  forego.  If  but  a  small 
fraction  of  these  economically  useless  expenditures  were  translated 
into  reductions  in  the  price  level,  the  gain  in  public  purchasing  power 
and  the  resulting  stimulus  to  production  and  employment  would  be 
material. 

During  recent  years,  there  has  been  a  very  marked  trend  in  the 
■direction  of  rendering  available  to  the  consumer  more  accurate  infor- 
mation— and  less  misinformation — regarding  the  character  of  the 
various  commodities  on  our  markets.  The  impetus  has  come  from 
a  number  of  sources.  Consumers  themselves  have  shown  a  growing- 
awareness  of  their  interest  and  have  formed  increasingly  effective, 
organizations.  Direct  pressure  has  been  exerted  upon  businessmen, 
particularly  upon  retailers,  to  furnish  adequate  technical  descriptions 
of  the  commodities  they  offer  for  sale.  Marked  success  has  been 
achieved  in  the  field  of  textile  fabrics;  accurate  designations  of  fiber 
content  and  weave  have  been  substituted  for  confusing  names  designed 
to  conceal  rather  than  to  reveal  the  true  nature  of  the  product.^ 

Businessmen,  intelligently  aware  of  their  self-interest,  have  con- 
tributed materially  in  many  fields.   Alarmed  by  the  unnecessary  and 

'  standard  specifications  developed  by  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  for  use  in  compiling  Its  retail  price 
•uata  have  stimulated  the  interest  of  many  retailei'S  in  the  accurate  designation  of  textile  products. 


5g  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

expensive  multiplication  of  grades  and  container  sizes,  they  have 
cooperated  with  Government  and  the  consumer  in  programs  of  simpli- 
fication. .  Canned  goods,  accurately  labeled  as  to  grade,  have  appeared 
on  the  market.  The  results  of  laboratory  tests  of  competing  products- 
have  been  publicized.  Of  course  these  moves  have  encountered 
material  resistance  but  they  have  progressed  notwithstanding. 

Finally  Government — both  Federal  and  State— has  intervened 
actively.  The  National  Bureau  of  Standards  has  cooperated  with 
industry  in  the  move  for  standardization.  The  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission and  the  Food  and  Drug  Administration  have  done  much  to 
combat  misrepresentation  and  to  further  informative  labeling.  Con- 
gress has  materially  facilitated  the  work  of  these  agencies  by  passing 
the  new  Food  and  Drug  Act  and  the  Wheeler-Lea  Act. 

To  summarize,  the  increasing  emphasis  upon  the  nonprice  aspects 
of  competition,  like  most  broad  economic  trends,  is  not  susceptible  to 
unqualified  appraisal.  In  part  it  is  an  inevitable  reflection  of  changing 
technology;  in  part  the  result  of  more  controllable  forces.  Some  of  its 
manifesta-tions  and  results  are  probably  desirable,  others  are  question- 
able, \v^hile  still  others  seem  definitely  to  impair  economic  efficiency. 

The  most  clearly  undesirable  aspects  of  this  trend  seem  to  arise 
from  coercive  and  collusive  devices  designed  to  restrain  or  eliminate 
price  competition.  Public  policy  has  been  traditionally  and  properly 
concerned  with  opposing  such  devices. 

At  the  same  time  Government  can  encourage,  both  by  cooperative 
and  by  regulatory  action,  the  improvement  of  comnxodity  information 
and  the  development  of  adequate  standards  of  quality  and  perform- 
ance. Such  a  program  seems  well  designed  to  discourage  inefTicient 
and  detrimental  manifestations  of  nonprice  competition. 

The  following  sections  of  this  chapter  do  not  present  a  compre- 
hensive record  either  of  the  causes  or  the  effects  of  nonprice  competi- 
tion. They  treat  a  few  outstanding  types  of  competitive  patterns, 
selected  partly  because  of  their  importance  and  partly  because  of  the 
availability  of  data  for  statistical  measures.  A  brief  review  of  somfe 
of  the  causes  and  implications  of  the  trend  away  from  jprice  competition 
is  first  presented,  followed  by  a  discussion  of  the  role  of  quality  as  an 
outstanding  focus  of  nonprice  competition.  Certain  specific  com- 
petitive techniques  are  then  examined  and  their  significance  to  the 
functioning  of  the  economy  appraised.  The  first  of  these  is  the  prac- 
tice of  price  lining  as  exemplifying  the  manner  in  which  business  con- 
vention may  alter  competitive  emphasis.  The  second  relates  to  the 
use  of  brands,  trade-marks,  and  fidvertising  as  means  of  distinguishing 
the  products  sold  by  business  rivals.  The  last  examines  the  way  in 
which  competitive  strategy  is  continually  altered  to  avoid  restraints 
imposed  upon  any  specific  form  of  competition  either  by  Government 
or  by  industry.  Finally,  the  conclusions  derived  from  this  analysis 
are  considered  in  their  relation  to  theforinulatjpn  of  Government  policy. 

PRICE  VERSUS  NONPRICE  COMPETITION — THE  SETTING  OF  THE  PROBLEM 

The  changing  jocus  oj  competition. — Many  recent  studies  of  the  work- 
ings of  our  economy  maintain  that  competition  has  for  years  been 
dechning  in  intensity  and  scope.     To  quote  from  one  of  these: 

An  industrial  organization  which  was  in  the  broad  sense  competitive  has 
become  diminishingly  so  during  the  past  half  century     *     *     * 

******* 


GONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  59 

Competiti^  o  capitalism  was  given  a  protracted  and  thorough  trial  in  the 
United  States  after  the  Civil  War.  Although  legal  institutions  were  framed 
with  a  broad  and  consistent  regard  for  the  assumptions  of  competition,  capitalism 
failed  to  preserve  its  competitive  quality     *     *     * 

******* 

The  rise  of  the  "heavy  industries,"  changes  in  methods  of  selling,  and  the 
widening  use  of  the  corporate  forms  of  business  organization  are  bringing,  if  they 
have  not  already  brought,  the  era  of  competitive  capitalism  to  a  close.* 

This  point  of  view  has,  of  course,  been  vigorously  challenged. 
Specific  illustrations  of  industries  in  which  competition  seems  to  have 
become  less  intense  during  the  past  generation  ape  countered  with 
examples  of  other  industries,  such  as  petroleum,  in  which  earlier 
monopolistic  controls  have  apparently  abated.  The  evidence  for 
either  side  is  largely  an  assembhng  of  individual  type  cases;  even  for 
those  the  data  available  often  permit,  conflicting  inferences.  More- 
over, agreement  is  even  lacking  as  to  prcciseh'  what  constitutes, 
competition.     Neither  set  of  arguments  seems  at  present  conclusive. 

Although  proof  of  the  thesis  that  competition  is  declining  appears 
inadequate,  there  is  abundant  evidence  that  the  focus  of  competitive 
effort  has  been  shifting.  In  many  sectors  of  the  economy  price  com- 
petition has  dwindled  in  importance  and  sometimes  even  disappeared. 
The  nonprice  aspects  of  competition  have  been  emphasized  instead. 

However,  this  redirection  of  competitive  strategy  cannot  of  itself 
be  accepted  as  synonymous  with  a  decline  of  competition.  In 
some  instances  it  has  probably  been  concurrent  with  an  actual  reduc- 
tion in  the  intensity  of  the  competitive  struggle;  nor  is  evidence  lacking 
that  this  has  at  times  been  its  specific  purpose.  Yet  there  are  cases, 
though  perhaps  less  typical,  in  which  the  converse  is  true  and  in  which 
emphasis  upon  factors  other  than  price  has  intensified  rather  than 
tempered  the  struggle  between  business  rivals.  What  the  net  result 
for  the  economy  has  been,  on  balance,  is  probably  impossible  to 
determine.  The  available  clues  are  fragmentary.  Intensity  of  com- 
petition is  an  abstract  concept,  not  susceptible  of  quantitative 
appraisal,^ 

Nor  docs  it  seem  particularly  important,  even  for  abstract  discus- 
sion, whether  the  trend  toward  nonprice  competition  has  or  has  not 
carried  with  it  an  appreciable  abatement  of  the  competitive  struggle. 
The  significant  issue,  from  the  standpoint  of  public  policy,  is  more 
immediate  and  practical.  The  forms  which  competition  takes 
intimately  affect  the  ways  in  whi^h  our  resources  are  utilized,  they 
influence  the  cyclical  swings  of  business  activity,  and,  in  the  long  run, 
the  consumer's  standard  of  living. 

Nonprice  competition  is  of  particular  importance  to  the  standard 
of  living  of  consumers  because  of  the  extent  to  which  it  affects  retail 
markets  and  the  everyday  necessities  of  life.  The  amount  which  a 
family  must  spend  for  food,  clothing,  groceries,  drugs,  and  cosmetics 
is  related  to  the  manner  in  which  business  concerns  selling  these  prod- 
ucts choose  to  compete,  by  their  decisions  to  stress  or  skimp  quality, 
to  advertise  more  or  less  intensively,  to  pack  simply  or  elaborately, 
to  favor  or  oppose  retail  price-cutting,  and  so  on.  This  is  clearly  a 
matter  of  broad  public  concern. 

*  The  Decline  of  Competition,  by  Arthur  E.  Burns,  1936,  pp.  v,  1,  40. 

'  However,  some  attempts  nave  been  mafie  to  measure  degree  of  monopoly  power.    See.  for;example — 

Michael  Kalocki— A  Theory  of  Commodity  Income  and  Capital  Taxation,  The  Economic  Journal,  Sep- 
tember 1937,  vol.  XLVII,  p.  444. 

A.  P.  Lcmer— The  Concept  of  Monopoly  and  the  Measurement  of  Monopoly  Powers,  The  Review  of 
Eeonomic  Studies,  vol.  I,  No.  3,  June  1934. 


60  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

A  wide  variety  of  forces  has  contributed  to  the  trend  away  from 
the  price  aspects  of  competition.  Some  of  these  have  been  considered 
eariier  in  this  report;  the  salient  points  will  be  repeated  here  for  the 
sake  of  completeness.  Among  the  most  important  of  these  forces  are 
the  technological  developments  of  recent  years,  reflected  in  the  in- 
creasing complexity,  dijfferentiation,  and  the  ever-changing  character 
of  the  commodities  on  our  markets.  As  commodities  increase  in 
number  and  complexity,  it  becomes  more  and  more  difficult  for  the 
purchasers  to  form  accurate  estimates  of  their  serviceability  and  utility. 
Price  differences  become  an  ever  less  satisfactory  yardstick  for  guiding 
the  buyer's  selection.  Even  the  most  expert  professional  purchasing 
agent  often  faces  great  difficulty  in  attempting  to  translate  physical 
product  differences  into  terms  of  price.  For  example,  the  calculations 
which  a  manufacturer  must  make  in  choosing  between  alternate  makes 
of  machinery  or  different  types  of  motive  power  unit  involve  a  host 
of  variables,  many  of  them  based  upon  hazardous  forecasts  of  future 
trends;  the  initial  price  may  be  only  a  very  minor  consideration. 
Even  the  raw  materials  of  industry  have  multiplied  amazingly.  Syn- 
thetic fibers,  new  alloys,  and  plastics  of  all  kinds  confront  the  industrial 
buyer  with  a  constantly  increasing  variety  of  choices  wliich  he  must 
make.  As  a  result,  the  significance  of  price  in  guiding  his  choice  is 
much  diminished. 

The  problems  of  the  expert  industrial  buyer,  difficult  as  they  are, 
are  far  less  overwhelming  than  those  which  the  technically  untrained 
consumer  faces.  There  are  today  relatively  few  products  on  retail 
markets  which  can  be  compared  upon  a  simple  price  basis.  Even 
apparently  standard  products  like  salt  or  sugar  have  been  packaged 
or  branded  in  such  a  way  as  to  discourage  reliance  upon  price  alone.* 

Increasing  product  complexity  and  differentiation  has  therefore 
limited  the  significance  of  price  comparisons,  while  it  has  correspond- 
ingly emphasized  the  nonprice  aspects  of  competition.  In  large  part, 
this  has  simply  reflected  the  inevitable  effects  of  technological  develop- 
ment. To  an  extent,  however,  there  has  been  a  deliberate  policy  on 
the  part  of  businessmen  to  accentuate  the  apparent  differences  between 
their  products  and  those  of  their  rivals,  for  the  specific  purpose  of 
diverting  competition  into  nonprice  channels. 

Many  businessmen,  probably  a  substantial  majority,  have  long  pre- 
ferred to  emphasize  the  nonprice  aspects  of  competition  and  to  subor- 
dinate price  appeal.  There  are  many  apparent  reasons  for  this  pref- 
erence. Perhaps  the  most  important  is  that  consumer  good  will  based 
upon  nonprice  factors  tends  to  be  more  lasting  than  that  depending 
simply  upon  price  appeal.  The  manufacturer  whose  sole  selling  argu- 
ment is  price  must  continue  to  undersell  his  competitors  indefinitely. 
Should  they  meet  his  offer,  his  advantage  is  gone.  On  the  other 
tand,  if  he  has  in  some  way  succeeded  in  creating  a  demand  among 
buyers  for  his  products  because  of  their  quality,  or  appearance,  or 
packaging,  or  through  the  effective  use  of  trade-marks  or  advertising, 
his  position  in  the  market  becomes  more  secure.  He  is  not  as  vulner- 
able to  price  reductions  made  by  his  competitors  as  would  be  true  if 
he  depended  exclusively  upon  price  appeal.  He  achieves  a  protected 
sector  of  the  m.arket  to  the  extent  to  which  buyers  have  become 
accustomed  to  attribute  especially  desirable  qualities  to  his  wares. 

•  For  afuller  discussioi:  of  the  effect  "of  brands  and  trade-marks  upon  price  competition,  see  pp.  75-90  below . 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  ^OWER  Ql 

With  it  he  also  attains  some  latitude  in  determining  his  own  price 
policy  without  the  need  of  constant  reference  to  what  his  rivals  are 
doing. 

In  a  sense,  the  maintenance  of  a  market  position  based  upon  non- 
price  appeal  requires  continual  vigilance  over  the  long  run,  just  as 
does  one  based  upon  price  appeal.  Thus,  good  will  built  up  by  the 
intensive  use  of  advertising  cannot  be  long  retained  if  the  advertising 
is  discontinued.  Nevertheless  most,  though  not  all,  businessmen 
seem  to  find  this  less  onerous  than  the  maintenance  of  a  poHcy  of 
continually  underselling  competitors. 

Moreover,  business  rivals  often  bitterly  resent  the  tactics  of  the 
firm  which  constantly  strives  to  undersell.  The  price  cutter  conse- 
quently risks  reprisals  in  the  form  of  retahatory  cuts,  which  often 
culminate  in  costly  price  wars.  Even  if  his  rivals'  products  or  prestige 
are  admittedly  superior,  they  are  often  reluctant  to  permit  him  to 
undersell  them  by  an  amount  sufficient  to  compensate  for  this 
disadvantage. 

From  the  point  of  view  of  the  seller,  price  appeal  also  has  a  certain 
disadvantage  in  that  its  value  can  be  measured  in  precise  terms. 
A  price  reduction  by  one  firm  loses  its  competitive  force  completely 
if  some  other  firm  exactly  matches  it.  On  the  other  hand,  even  an 
intrinsically  insignificant  change  in  the  character  of  the  product  or  in 
the  context  of  its  advertising  cannot  often  be  matched  so  exactly, 
and  the  advantage  gained  thereby  is  more  hkely  to  persist.^ 

As  the  business-getting  potentialities  of  nonprice  competition  have 
been  more  thoroughly  explored,  price  competition  has  fallen  not  only 
into  disfavor  but  also  into  disrepute.  Many  trade  associations  have 
-condi  cted  long  and  vigorous  campaigns  to  persuade  their  members 
'that  price  cutting  is  an  unethical  practice;  today  the  price  cutter  is 
'videly  considered  a  chiseler.  The  value  of  price  reductions  in  expand- 
ing markets  has  been  ignored  or  underemphasized ;  it  is  contended 
instead  that  they  disrupt  the  standards  of  an  industry  and  create 
distress  to  all  its  members.  Price  "stabilization"  is  held  forth  as  the 
desired  goal. 

A  frank  expression  of  this  point  of  view  by  a  prominent  industrial 
engineer  and  trade  association  manager  follows: 

If  I  were  in  a  position  to  write  the  ticket  for  industry  in  this  country,  I  should 
give  each  industry  the  right  to  name  the  prices  at  which  its  products  should  be 
sold,  and  I  should  enforce  these  price  determinations  through  the  due  process  of 
law.  In  my  opinion,  these  prices  should  be  based  on  certain  factors  which  would 
insure  absolute  fairness  and  equality  of  treatment  to  capital,  management,  labor, 
and  consumers — four  factors  involved  in  every  transaction.  I  should  determine 
these  prices  on  the  average  industry  cost,  using  replacement  costs  for  raw  material, 
adequate  wage  rates  for  labor,  and  overheads  based  on  a  reasonable  use  of  the 
facilities  of  the  industry.  I  should  not  expect  this  cost  to  include  carrying  charges 
on  idle,  unused,  or  excessive  capacity.  Executive  salaries  should  be  checked  and 
should  bear  a  reasonable  relationship  to  the  size  of  the  company'  involved.^ 

Among  those  who  advocate  eliminating  price  competition  are  many 
who  hold  no  strong  brief  for  the  nonprice  forms  of  competition  either. 
Some  at  least  are  striving  toward  a  market  in  which  each  firm  is  con- 
tent with  its  allotted  share  of  the  total  business  available,  and  makes 

'  Of  course  some  nonprice  features— e.  g.,  the  terms  of  a  guarantee— can  be  matched  just  as  precisely  as 
price.    Nevertheless,  the  proposition  is  broadly  valid. 

•  Stevenson,  Charles  R.,  Price  Control  and  the  Allotment  of  Business — address  delivered  before  the 
National  Association  of  Cost  Accountants,  June  26, 1934. 


02  CONOBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

no  effort  to  increase  that  share  by  the  use  of  either  price  or  nonprice 
tactics.  The  ehmination  of  price  competition  is  to  some  people  merely 
a  step  to  the  ultimate  goal,  the  elimination  of  all  effective  competition. 
As  a  preliminary  step,  however,  they  prefer  to  see  sales  effort  devoted 
to  nonprice  channels  as  a  less  obnoxious  form  of  rivalry  for  business. 

The  development  of  certain  business  customs  and  conventions  has 
also  served  to  divert  competition  from  price  channels.  Among  the 
more  important  of  these  is  the  establishment  of  fairly  rigid."  price  lines" 
for  a  wide  variety  of  commodities.  The  effects  of  this  practice  are 
considered  subsequently.     (See  pp.  70-75.) 

Whether  on  grounds  of  expediency,  custom,  or  ethics,  therefore, 
the  business  world  at  large,  with  some  notable  exceptions,  has  (?ome  to 
frown  upon  price  competition.  In  order  to  make  this  disapproval 
effective,  ingenuous  techniques  have  been  devised  for  eliminating 
price  competition  by  fixing  (or  more  euphemistically  "stabUizing") 
prices  in  many  lines  of  industry.  Many  of  these  have  proved  extremely 
effective.  This  phase  of  the  subject,  however,  is  not  within  the 
province  of  this  report. 

At  times  Government,  both  Federal  and  State,  has  intervened  in 
ways  calculated  to  limit  the  freedom  of  price  competition.  The  most 
comprehensive  step  of  this  kiad  was  the  regulation  of  trade  practices 
under  the  N.  R.  A.  At  the  present  time  such  regulation  is  much  more 
narrowly  confined,  existing  primarily  in  the  field  of  public  utility 
rates,  of  bituminous  coal,  and  of  certain  farm  products. 

In  addition  to  such  direct  fixing  of  prices,  other  kinds  of  legislation 
have  served  to  limit  price  competition  to  some  degree.  For  example, 
the  Fair  Trade  Acts  which  are  now  in  force  in  44  States,  together  with 
the  MUler-Tydings  Enabling  A^t,  permit  manufacturers  to  fix  mjii- 
mum  resale  prices  for  articles  bearing  their  identifying  brand  or  trade- 
mark. As  between  retailers,  therefore,  competition,  on  the  sale  of 
items  of  the  classes  affected,  particularly  of  drugs*,  toiletries,  cos- 
metics, books,  and  liquors  has  been  forced  to  a  considerable  extent  into 
nonprice  channels. 

Many  States  have  enacted  Unfair  Practices  Acts  which  prohibit 
sales  below  cost,  with  the  term  *'cost"  defined  in  various  ways.  While 
these  laws  do  not  of  themselves  suppress  price  competition,  there  is 
some  evidence  that  trade  associations  in  a  number  of  areas  have  used 
them  as  a  vehicle  for  fairly  rigid  price  control. 

Mention  may  also  be  made  of  the  antidiscrimination  laws,  such  as 
the  Robinson-Patman  Act,  though  their  effect  is  somewhat  less 
obvious.  To  the  extent  to  which  sellers  are  required  to  maintain 
uniform  prices  to  all  buyers,  they  are  rendered  unable  to  seek  particular 
sales  by  cutting  prices.  If  they  choose  to  rely  upon  price  competition 
as  their  primary  sales  argument,  they  must  cut  prices  simultaneously 
to  all  comers.  Naturally,  many  sellers  are  far  more  reluctant  to  take 
such  a  broad  step  than  to  reduce  prices  on  individual  transactions. 
In  this  way,  therefore,  antidiscrimination  laws  may  restrict  ■  price 
competition  and  may  favor  the  emphasis  of  nonprice  factors. 

Numerous  other  developments  have  undoubtedly  affected  the  trend 
away  from  price  competition.  For  example,  changes  in  market 
structure,  such  as  the  number  of  buyers  or  sellers  in  a  given  market  or 
modifications  in  channels  of  distribution  have  exercised  an  influejice 
upon    the    focus   of   competitive   strategy.     However,    such    forces, 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  g3 

important  as  they  be,  have  been  less  consistent  in  their  direction  and 
perhaps  less  significant  in  their  net  effect  than  those  which  have  been 
]ust  discussed. 

Prices  related  to  nonprice  elements  of  the  transaction. — So  far,  the 
terms  "price  competition"  and  "nonprice  competition"  have  been 
used  broadly  to  denote  different  general  patterns  through  which  busi- 
ness rivalry  expresses  itself.  Actually,  of  course,  they  are  not  mutu- 
ally exclusive  terms  and  it  is  difficult  to  draw  the  precise  boundary 
between  the  two. 

A  host  of  elements  enter  into  the  exchange  between  the  buyer  and 
seller  which  constitutes  the  general  business  transaction.  Some  of 
these,  as,  for  example,  trade  discounts,  are  clearly  translatable  into 
terms  of  exact  price  equivalents.  Others,  such  as  brand  prestige,  or 
streamlined  design,  or  neon  lights  in  front  of  a  retail  store,  are  not 
translatable  into  price  equivalents  and  may,  therefore,  be  considered 
forms  of  nonprice  competition. 

In  between,  however,  there  is  a  wide  variety  of  elements  on  the 
border  line  which  cannot  be  clearly  assigned  to  either  category. 
Premiums  offered  in  connection  with  sales  at  retail  constitute  one 
example.  Sometimes  the  premium  offered  is  of  a  character  which  may 
be  Considered  the  direct  equivalent  of  a  monetary  rebate,  as  in  the 
case  of  profit-sharing  coupons,  or  it  may  take  the  form  of  some 
specific  article  whose  value  is  readily  measurable  in  terms  of  doUars 
and  cents.  Presumably,  premiums  of  this  kind  might  be  considered 
forms  of  price  competition.  On  the  other  hand,  many  premiums  have 
a  less  tangitjje  valiie,  as  in  the  case  of  pins  denoting  a  child's  member- 
ship in  some  club  organized  for  advertising  purposes.  Similarly 
credit  terms,  particularly  on  conditional  sales,  have  both  price 
aspects,  such  as  the  rate  of  interest,  and  nonprice  aspects,  such  as  the 
form  of  security  demanded  or  the  conditions  under  which  the  article 
sold  may  be  repossessed.  Guarantees  expressed  in  general  terms,  or 
which  fall  well  within  the  expected  performance  of  the  merchandise  in 
question  are  largely  of  a  nonprice  nature ;  however,  if  the  guarantee 
stipulates  a  specific  performance,  with  a  bonus  for  exceeding  the 
guarantee  and  a  penalty  for  failing  to  come  up  to  it,  the  price  aspect 
may  be  paramount.  Certain  elements  of  quality  yield  satisfactions 
difficult  to  measure  in  terms  of  price;  others  such  as  the  heat  content 
of  fuels  or  the  tensQe  strength  of  steel  are  often  directly  translatable 
into  price  equivalents. 

It  is  apparent,  therefore,  that  no  strict  line  of  demarcation  between 
price  competition  and  nonprice  competition  is  practicable.  Conse- 
quently the  two  terms  should  be  understood  to  relate  to  broad  trends 
of  business  strategy  rather  than  to  any  specific  practice  or  set  of 
practices. 

ASPECTS    OF    NONPRICE    COMPETITION 

Quality  and  performance. — Perhaps  the  most  important  single  avenue 
through  which  nonprice  competition  expresses  itself  is  the  actual 
physical  quality  or  content  of  the  goods  involved.  Of  all  the  nonprice 
elements  entering  into  the  ordinary  transaction,  this  seems  to  be  the 
most  universally  significant.  Moreover,  it  is  probably  the  outstand- 
ing single  factor  conditioning  the  interpretation  of  price  statistics. 

QuaUt^  itself  is  by  no  means  a  simple  concept.  For  any  single 
commodity  it  may  invohe  a  host  of  variables.     In  the  case  of  auto- 


g4  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

mobiles,  for  example,  any  appraisal  of  quality  must  include  durability, 
gasoline  consumption,  probable  frequency  and  cost  of  the  necessary 
repairs,  appearance,  comfort,  riding  qualities,  safety,  ease  of  manipu- 
lation, "brilliance"  of  performance,  and  so  on  almost  indefinitely. 
Each  one  of  these  may  be  subdivided  further;  thus  economy  of  opera- 
tion is  a  function  of  the  speed  at  which  the  car  is  to  be  driven,  as  well 
as  of  the  roads  over  which  it  will  be  used.  Some  of  these  character- 
istics, e.  g.,  gasoline  consumption,  may  be  expressible  in  quantitative 
terms.    Others,  such  as  appearance,  defy  such  measurement. 

All  of  these  factors  modify  the  significance  of  price  quotations. 
Some,  as  has  been  said,  are  relatively  concrete  and  tangible;  for 
example,  it  is  possible  to  arrive  at  estimates  of  the  durability  of  cer- 
tain kinds  of  goods.  Chart  VIII  compares  the  price  of  automobile  tire 
casings  with  their  average  life  during  the  last  27  years.  Between 
1913  and  1937  average  tire  life  in  years  more  than  tripled;  during  the 
shorter  period' since  1926,  there  was  an  increase  of  almost  70  percent. 
La  terms  of  mileage,  the  increase  in  durability  was  undoubtedly  even 
greater,  since  the  average  car  travels  much  farther  in  a  year  than  was 
true  20  or  30  years  ago.  It  is  apparent  that  the  trend  of  the  prices 
charged  for  automobile  tires  tells  only  part  of  the  story. 

Similarly,  in  the  case  of  mechanical  refrigerators  there  has  been  a 
substantial  increase  in  durability  since  1920,  although  the  change 
during  the  past  decade  has  not  been  so  great.  In  1920  the  average 
life  expectancy  was  6  years;  in  1926  it  was  1 1  years;  in  1930  it  was  13 
years,  and  today  it  is  15  years. 

Economy  of  operation  .is  another  element  of  quality  competition 
which  may  be  approximately  measurable.  For  example,  the  average 
current  consumption  for  6-cubic-foot  electrical  refrigerators  was  re- 
duced 21  percent  between  1931  and  1938.^ 

Similarly,  according  to  a  recent  study,  operating  costs  per  mile  for 
automobiles  were  reduced  by  more  than  40  percent  between  1925  and 
1937;  a  significant  component  of  this  reduction  was  a  decline  of  almost 
70  percent  in  repair  expenses  per  mile.^° 

A  comprehensive  survey  of  some  of  the  more  measurable  elements 
of  quality  in  the  case  of  farm  machinery  was  published  by  the  Amer- 
ican Society  of  Agricultural  Engineers  in  1933."  This  study  sought 
to  appraise  these  changes  in  quality  in  quantitative  terms.  It  was 
concluded  that  changes  in  a  wide  variety  of  operating  characteristics 
between  1910-14  and  1932  could  be  expressed  as  composite  percent- 
ages of  improvement.'^ 

»  According  to  tests  made  in  1931  by  the  Procurement  Division  of  the  Treasury,  the  average  consumption 
of  a  6-cubic-foot  refrigerator  (five  makes)  was  44  liilowatt-hours  per  month.  In  1938  a  test  based  on  14  makes 
of  refrigerators  showed  that  the  6-foot  box  was  consuming  on  the  average  only  35  kilowatt-hours  per  month. 

'«  TheDynamicsof  Automobile  Demand,  General  Motors  Corporation,  1939;  p.  117.  (Part  of  this  decline 
in  operating  costs  is  attributable  to  the  lower  prices  and  greater  durability  of  tires.) 

"  Report  of  an  Inquiry  into  Changes  in  Quality  Values  of  Farm  Machines  Between  1910-14  and  1932 
pt.  I,  pp.  5  and  6. 

n  Quoting  from  this  report: 

"It  was  also  decided  to  limit  the  study  to  25  typical  farm  implements  already  highly  developed  and  in 
general  use  in  the  pre-war  period,  and  not  to  go  into  the  field  of  automobiles,  trucks,  and  tractors  which, 
owing  to  their  later  development,  present  different  questions  and  would  call  for  a  separate  study. 

"Changes  in  the  design,  material,  or  construction  of  a  farm  machine,  or  any  part  thereof,  may  add  to  its 
quality  value  in  a  number  of  ways,  of  which  the  following  are  worthy  of  special  consideration: 

"1.  Greater  durability  and  prcduciive  usefulvess.— The  value  of  this  quality  is  measured  In  terms  of  units  of 
service  rendered  during  the  life  of  the  machine,  such  as  acres  oT  land  plowed,  planted,  cultivated,  or. har- 
vested; bushels  of  grain  threshed  or  shelled;  pounds  of  food  ground;  quantity  of  cream  separated,  etc. 

"2.  Reduction  in  the  replacement  of  wearing  parts. — Most  machines  have  certain  parts  which  in  normal  use 
are  subject  to  wear.  Farm  machines  are  so  designed  as  to  make  the  replacement  of  these  wearing  parts 
convenient.    The  use  of  wear-resistant  materials,  such  as  heat-treated  or  alloy  steels  and  corrosion-resisting 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


65 


QQ  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Quality  changes  are  not  usually-  thought  of  in  connection  with 
such  relatively  standard  items  as  steel,  yet  even  here  they  may  be 
of  material  importance.  Thus,  during  the  last  15  years  there  have 
been  distinct  improvements  in  the  quality  of  ordinary  structural  steel. 
Government  specifications  in  1933  stipulated  an  ultimate  tensile 
strength  of  55,000  to  65,000  pounds  per  square  inch  with  a  minimum 
yield  point  of  30,000  pounds.  Present  specifications  called  for  an 
ultimate  tensile  strength  of  between  60,000  and  72,000  pounds  with 
a  minimum  yield  point  of  33,000  pounds  per  square  inch.  These 
changes  have  been  reflected  in  modifications  of  standard  design  re- 
quirements. For  example,  12  j^ears  ago  the  Procurement  Division 
based  its  structural  steel  design  upon  a  working  strength  of  16,000 
pounds  per  square  inch.  As  the  quality  of  steel  improved,  the  work- 
ing strength  was  increased  to  18,000  pounds  and,  5  years  ago,  to 
20,000  pounds  per  square  inch.    In  other  words,  the  tonnage  of  steel 

materials,  not  only  means  less  expense  for  replacement  parts,  but  less  labor  and  time  are  required  for  re- 
placements. 

"3.  Redaction  in  loss  of  time  due.  to  failure  of  machines  to  function  continuously. —The  value  of  fnrm  machines 
(through  improvement  in  design)  is  advanced  by  their  ability  to  operate  continuously  without  delay  due 
to  choking,  clogging,  or  the  failure  of  any  part  to  function  properly 

"4.  Less  breakage  of  machine  parts.— The.  making  of  machine  parts  of  the  proper  design  and  of  high-quality, 
reliable  materials  results  not  only  in  a  reduction  of  the  expense  for  broken  parts,  but  also  in  a  saving  of  labor 
and  time  for  making  the  repairs.  Furthermore,  owing  to  the  importance  of  timeliness  for  many  farm  oper- 
ations, the  dependability  and  freedom  from  breakdown  of  a  farm  machine  is  of  great  value.  Many  safety 
features,  such  as  spring  releases  for  plows,  have  been  introduced  to  protect  machines  from  breakage. 

"5.  Increased  efficiency  in  the  use  of  energy. — The  value  of  a  farm  machine  is  raised  when  a  stated  amount 
of  useful  work  can  be  accomplished  with  the  consumption  of  less  energy  or  power.  Increased  efficiency  is 
secured  by  the  elimination  of  friction  losses  through  the  use  of  friction-reducing  bearings,  better  lubrication, 
and  also  by  the  introduction  of  mechanisms  and  features  of  design  by  which  energy  is  applied  more  effec- 
tively to  the  work  to  be  accomplished.  For  instance,  the  advance  in  the  design  and  manufacture  of  silo 
fillers,  or  ensilage  cutters,  has  resulted  in  easily  doubling  the  output  of  useful  work  per  unit  of  energy  con- 
sumed. 

"6.  Increased  capacity  of  machine. — With  the  use  of  better  design,  better  quality  materials,  and  improved 
construction,  the  capacity  of  many  machines  may  be  increased  b>  ^  permissible  higher  speed  of  operation. 
Most  field  and  belt-driven  machines  may  now  be  operated  at  higher  speeds  with  a  corresponding  increase 
in  output. 

"7.  Improved  operating  efficiency. — This  quality  is  represented  by  the  more  efficient  functioning  of  ma- 
chines such  as  the  more  thorough  elimination  of  weeds  through  cultivation,  the  harvesting  of  a  crop  with 
less  waste,  or  the  removal  of  waste  and  weed  seed  from  threshed  grain. 

"8.  Improvement  in  operating  precision.— Although  related  to  operating  eflSciency,  precision  in  operation 
and  control  represents  a  value  not  wholly  covered  by  this  term.  This  characteristic  is  indicated  clearly  by 
accuracy  in  seeding  machines,  fertilizer  machines,  control  of  machines,  etc. 

"9.  Reduction  in  time  required  to  care  for  machines. — The  time  required  to  properly  care  for  the  lubrication 
and  adjustment  of  machines  may  be  an  important  consideration  as  the  output  of  useful  work  is  influenced 
thereby.  Many  current  machines  require  lubrication  only  one-tenth  as  often  as  earlier  machines  on  account 
of  enclosure  of  working  parts,  improved  oilers,  grease  cups,  etc. 

"10.  Reduction  in  lost  time  and  expense  due  to  accidents. — Important  advances  have  been  made  in  protecti'ng 
life  and  limb  by  safety  releases,  better  guarding  of  working  parts,  etc.,  reducing  the  loss  in  time  and  money 
caused  by  accidents. 

"11.  Greater  economy  through  improved  operating  devices. — Power  lifts,  balancing  springs,  convenient  levers, 
and  adjusting  devices  make  it  possible  to  operate  machines  with  a  saving  of  time  and  effort. 

"12.  Increased  efficiency  through  lessening  operator's  fatigue. — A  more  comfortable  and  efiScient  position  for 
the  operator,  better  protection  for  him  from  dirt  and  dust,  and  elimination  of  excessive  vibrations  contribute 
definitely  to  the  value  of  a  machine,  making  possible  more  continuous  operation  over  longer  work  periods. 

"Being  already  familiar  to  a  considerable  extent  with  the  construction,  field  operation,  and  testing  of  farm 
machines,  and  the  changes  therein  during  the  period  under  consideration,  the  authors  felt  that  their  task 
should  be  primarily  one  of  inspection,  comparison,  and  appraisal  rather  than  actual  field  tests.  Obviously 
the  time  and  expense  required  would  completely  prohibit  determination  through  following  and  comparing 
the  operation  of  1910-14  and  1932  machines  of  the  same  type  and  purpose  under  varying  conditions  of  soil, 
crop,  and  climate. 

"Accord  ingly,  the  authors  made  a  detailed  examination  of  twenty-five  machines  of  1932  in  comparison  with 
similar  machines  of  1910-14  at  the  plants  of  three  prominent  farm-machinery  manufacturers  where  machines 
of  both  periods  were  made  available,  together  with  the  engineering  records  and  data  relating  thereto.  Be- 
sides comparing  and  checking  the  machines  part  by  part,  the  authors  also  questioned  at  length  a  number  of 
tngineers  who  have  been  devoting  themselves  to  the  development  of  these  particular  machines  during  the 
past  25  years. 

"In  addition,  the  authors  were  provided'  with  chronological  record  of  changes  in  machines,  reports  on 
elaborate  and  extended  shop  and  field  tests  made  to  determme  the  results  of  these  changes,  and  the  findings 
and  opinions  of  the  engineers  in  question.  The  authors  also  called  for  and  were  supplied  with  data  bearing 
on  the  reduction  in  the  demand  from  farmers  for  certain  repair  parts  after  changes  were  made,  and  on  this 
point  were  convinced  that  in  many  instances  such  reductions  were  extensive  and  signiicant. 

"Further,  in  order  to  evaluate  more  accurately  the  effect  of  changes  in  the  life  and  performance  of  the 
machines  considered,  accelerated  tests  of  wearing  parts  were  made  and  laboratory  tests  of  m&ny  important 
typical  Darts,  old  and  new,  were  conducted  in  the  presence  of  the  authors. 

"The  various  changes  in  each  of  the  25  types  of  machines  and  the  conclusions  of  the  authors  with  respect  to 
their  separate  and  combined  effect  on  quality  values  are  set  forth  fully  in  the  detailed  studies  of  each  machine 
contained  in  this  report." 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  07 

required  for  a  specific  structure  can  be  substantially  less  today  than 
it  was  before  these  changes  in  specifications  and  in  design  require- 
ments. At  the  same  time  efiicient,  wide  flanged  shapes  were  intro- 
duced following  the  development  of  new.  types  of  rolls  for  I  beams; 
these  new  shapes  have  also  permitted  lighter  and  more  economical 
design. 

Many  other  criteria  of  quality  are  subject  to  some  sort  of  concrete 
measurement  or  specification.  Among  these  may  be  listed  the  fiber 
content  or  construction  of  cloths,  the  fabric  and  some  aspects  of  the 
workmanship  of  apparel,  the  leather  used  in  footwear,  the  quality  of 
certain  foods  for  which  grades  have  been  established,  the  metal  con- 
tent of  silverware,  etc.  All  of  these  elements  are  to  some  extent 
physically  determinable.  It  is  manifestly  impossible  to  compile  a 
complete  list. 

As  a  rule  it  is  difficult  or  impossible  to  translate  these  quality 
changes  into  price  equivalents;  the  significance  of  price  indexes  based 
upon  quoted  prices  is  limited  accordingly.  For  automobiles,  which 
are  of  course  exceedingly  complex,  there  has  been  an  attempt  to  devise 
a  price  index  which  would  show  changes  not  only  in  price  but  also  in 
weight,  wheel  base,  and  horsepower  expressed  in  terms  of  price.  The 
technique  used  involves  many  assumptions  and  a  complex  statistical 
procedure;  it  is  mentioned  here  merely  to  illustrate  the  variety  and 
significance  of  the  many  components  of  quality.^^ 

In  addition  to  variables  of  this  kind,  there  is  a  wide  variety  of  less 
tangible  factors  entering  into  the  concept  of  quality  which  cannot 
yield  to  any  form  of  precise  specification.  Yet  these  intangible 
elements  are  often  of  primary  competitive  importance;  they  may 
largely  determine  the  consumer  acceptance  of  a  product  and  must  be 
considered  in  any  interpretation  of  price  behavior.  In  the  case  of 
apparel,  for  example,  the  consumer  is  more  interested  in  the  elusive 
element  of  style  than  in  physical  specifications  of  cloth  or  workman- 
ship. Similarly  in  the  sale  of  food,  the  purely  subjective  factor  of  taste 
or  flavor  may  largely  determine  the  popularity  or  failure  of  the  prod- 
uct. Reverting  again  to  automobiles,  the  success  of  a  model  may  be 
more  directly  affected  by  the  design  or  ornamentation  of  its  hood 
than  by  the  efficiency  of  its  carburetor.  The  color  of  bathroom 
fixtures  may  exercise  a  not  inconsiderable  weight  upon  a  prospect's 
decision  to  purchase  or  rent  a  home. 

Some  of  these  elements  of  style,  appearance,  or  comfort  may  have 
a  relation  to  objectively  measurable  characteristics.  For  example, 
it  may  be  that  most  consumers  prefer  the  flavor  of  canned  foods 
meeting  the  grade  A  requirements  of  the  Bureau  of  Agricultural 
Economics  to  those  which  would  be  classed  as  grade  C.  Attractive 
style  is  often  associated  with  superior  workmanship.  Yet  such 
relations  are  often  fortuitous.  A  high  quahty  grade  is  not  a  necessary 
guarantee  of  desirable  flavor;  conversely,  many  may  prefer  the  flavor 
of  certain  grade  C  products  to  others  classed  in  grade  A.     In  general, 

"  Andrew  T.  Court  describes  this  attempt  to  devise  a  hedocic  price  index  in  The  Dynamics  of  Auto- 
mobile Demand,  op.  cit.,  pp.  99-117.  His  procedure  was  based  upon  computing  equations  of  multiple 
regression  for  price  in  terms  of  weight,  wheel  base,  and  horsepower  for  the  standard  models  of  all  the  more 
important  makes  of  cars  during  each  year.  This  technique  was  designed  to  determine  the  valuation  placed 
by  the  market  upon  each  of  these  factors.  Court  listed,  in  addition,  various  other  determinable  elements 
of  quality,  such  as  tire  section,  the  period  of  the  front  spring,  front  seat  width,  top  speed,  rate  of  deceleration 
and  acceleration,  rate  of  depreciation,  etc.  Of  course  any  important  change  in  design  affecting  the  signifl- 
cance  of  any  of  these  elements,  such  as  the  introduction  of  a  new  lightweight  structural  alloy,  would  seriously 
impair  the  usefulness  of  an  index  of  this  kind. 


gg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

the  preference  or  whim  of  consumers  cannot  be  confined  within  rigid, 
definable  categories.  .  . 

It  is  apparent,  then,  that  the  range  of  quaUty  competition  may 
extend  from  such  precisely  measurable  characteristics  as  durabiUty, 
operating  economy,  tensile  strength,  or  fuel  value  to  such  relatively 
indefinable  elements  as  taste,  style,  comfort,  or  exclusiveness. 

The  degree  to  which  any  of  these  factors  is  actually  emphasized  in 
business  sales  strategy  varies  widely  for  different  commodities.  Thus, 
in  sales  to  expert  buyers  (e.  g.,  industrial,  institutional,  or  Govern- 
ment purchasing  agents)  technical  specifications  and  tested  char- 
acteristics of  performance  are  usually  more  important  than  such 
elements  as  style  or  appearance.  In  deahng  with  the  comparatively 
imtrained  ultimate  consumer,  on  the  other  hand,  less  stress  usually 
is  laid  upon  performance  data  and  more  upon  style,  taste,  and  eye- 
catching features. 

The  focus  of  competition  is  materially  affected  by  the  degree  to 
which  any  element  of  the  transaction  has  become  standardized  by 
business  practice,  or  custom,  or  by  Government  regulation.  Thus  it 
has  been  pointed  out  that  price  uniformity  favors  the  shift  of  com- 
petitive pressure  into  nonprice  channels.  Similarly  the  standardiza- 
tion of  any  element  of  quality  necessarily  reduces  its  value  as  a  selling 
argument.  The  increase  in  tensile  strength  of  structural  steel  is  of 
considerable  importance  in  the  interpretation  of  price  statistics; 
however,  since  all  steel  plants  are  equipped  to  produce  the  same  grade 
of  steel,  it  is  not  a  basis  for  rivalry  between  them. 

To  the  individual  seller,  therefore,  certain  phases  of  quality  com- 
petition involve  problems  similar  to  those  which  have  been  described 
in  connection  with  price  competition.  Where  changes  in  quality  are 
such  that  they  can  'be  accurately  measured  and  precisely  duplicated, 
their  efficacy  as  a  competitive  weapon  is  thereby  limited. 

The  following  quotation  expresses  this  dilemma  which  faces  rival 
sellers  when  their  products  approach  imiformity: 

The  selling  of  refrigerators  requires  the  massing  of  all  conceivable  sales  influ- 
ences. It  becomes  evident  to  one  who  compares  the  methods  of  the  leading 
companies  that  mere  sharp  angles  will  not  sell  refrigerators  any  more.  As  an 
industry  matures,  angles  disappear  and  products  approach  uniformity.  Adver- 
tising at  the  same  time  takes  on  a  similarity. 

Probably  nothing  is  so  striking  about  the  refrigerator  advertising  as  its  simi- 
larity. Probably  no  one  feels  this  more  keenly  than  the  advertisers  themselves. 
Assuming  that  .Joe  Doakes,  the  common  man,  has  an  analytical  mind,  he  doubtless 
compares  the  advertising  of  the  leading  makes  with  growing  confusion.  It  is 
certainly  impossible  for  him  to  decide  from  the  advertising  which  of  them  is  best 
for  his  purposes." 

Conseauentlv,  there  has  been  some  oendency  for  sales  emphasis  to 
shift  to  tnese  elements  of  quality  which  cannot  be  so  readily  imitated, 
particularly  for  consumers'  goods.  Sellers  of  groceries  rarely  mention 
their  conformity  with  government  standards  of  quality;  sellers  of 
dresses  do  not  usually  emphasize  fiber  content;'^  cosngetics  are  com- 
monly sold  without  reference  to  the  quality  of  their  ingredients. 
Instead  it  is  flavor,  style,  or  attractive  containers  which  constitute 
the  focus  of  interest.  Distinctive  appeal  is  far  more  readily  attained 
on  the  basis  of  the  latter  elements  of  quahty  than  on  that  of  the  former, 
and  is  subject  to  ingenious  variation  to  maintain  leadership. 

'<  Printers'  Ink  Monthly,  August  1937. 

'•There  has  been  a  growinp  tendency  to  indicate  the  fiber  content  of  apparel  on  the  label,  partly  as  a  result 
of  Federal  Trade  Commission  activity.    However,  style  usually  reinnins  the  primary  form  of  competition. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  59 

Guarantees. — Closely  akin  to  quality  as  a  basis  for  competition  are 
guarantees  offered  by  the  seller.  For  example,  an  important  consid- 
eration in  connection  with  the  purchase  of  an  automobile  is  the  dura- 
tion of  the  period  diu^ing  which  the  seller  guarantees  to  remedy  any 
defects  free  of  charge.  This  is  perhaps  even  more  important  in  the 
case  of  used  cars  than  in  the  new  car  market.  The  average  purchaser 
would  prefer  to  pay  substantially  more  for  an  automobile  purchased 
from  a  reputable  dealer  than  for  one  bought  directly  from  its  private 
owner,  because  of  the  possibility  of  recourse  in  the  former  case  for 
defects  which  are  not  observed  at  the  time  of  purchase.  Automobile 
tires  have  already  been  mentioned  as  an  outstanding  example  of  the 
importance  of  the  guarantee.  In  the  case  of  electric  refrigerators  the 
general  practice  is  to  guarantee  replacement  of  cabinets,  shelves,  trays, 
accessories,  refrigeration  imit,  and  controls  in  case  they  become  un- 
satisfactory within  one  year  of  purchase  due  to  any  defects  in  manu- 
facture. In  addition,  the  refrigeration  unit  is  commonly  guaranteed 
for  an  additional  4  years.  In  some  cases  this  latter  guarantee  is 
included  as  part  of  the  purchase  price.  In  others,  the  guarantee  is 
optional  with  the  purchaser;  he  can,  if  he  wishes,  pay  an  additional 
$5  for  this  added  protection.  Here  there  seemi3  to  be  a  direct  equiva- 
lence between  the  price  difference  and  the  guarantee. 

From  the  competitive  standpoint,  simple  guarantees  of  this  charac- 
ter are  subject  to  somewhat  the  same  hmitations  as  price  appeal. 
Their  terms  can  be  matched  exactly;  once  a  practice  has  become  uni- 
form in  the  industry,  the  offer  of  the  guarantee  is  no  longer  a  competi- 
tive asset.  Thus,  the  present  system  of  refrigerator  guarantees  seems 
to  have  become  the  general  practice  in  1936.  The  effect  of  this 
uniformity  is  commented  upon  in  an  editorial  in  a  trade  publication: 

"is  the  6-tear  guarantee  necessary 

"A  recent  trip  into  the  field  reveals  the  fact  that  electric  dealers  are  highly 
dissatisfied  with  the  epidemic  of  5-year  guarantees  which  seem  to  have  broken 
out  in  the  national  advertising  of  the  electric  refrigerators. 

"Originally  the  guarantee  found  an  excuse  for  itself  in  that  it  was  the  exclusive 
promise  of  one  company  and  so  formed  a  sales  argument  for  the  salesmen  handling 
that  line.  Now,  when  practically  every  manufacturer  makes  the  same  promise,  it  does 
not  even  offer  a  talking  point  against  rival  makes. "^^     (Italics  supplied.) 

Other  common  forms  of  guarantee  are  often  important  aspects  of 
the  transaction.  Thus,  certain  sets  of  china  and  glassware  are  sold 
with  the  guarantee  that  additional  pieces  can  be  purchased  as  desired, 
usually  for  stipulated  periods  of  years.  These  so-called  open  sets 
may  sell  for  substantially  higher  prices  than  other  sets  of  identical 
quality. 

In  the  wholesale  markets,  an  important  form  of  guarantee  is  the 
guarantee  against  price  decline.  For  example,  the  purchaser  of  fer- 
tilizer may  be  protected  against  any  reduction  in  the  price  level  during 
the  balance  of  the  selling  season.  Sometimes  such  guarantees  extend 
only  to  price  changes  by  the  specific  producer  involved;  sometimes 
the  buyer  is  protected  against  any  price  reduction  initiated  by  any 
important  competing  seller.  Guarantees  of  this  latter  kind  greatly 
limit,  if  they  do  not  eliminate,  the  scope  of  price  competition.  They 
make  it  unnecessary  for  the  purchaser  to  compare  competing  price 
offers  or  to  delay  his  buying  in  anticipation  of  future  market  declines. 

"  Electrical  Merchandising,  December  1936,  p.  22. 


7Q  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Price  guarantees  may  also  have  the  collateral  effect  of  reducing  price 
flexibiuty  during  the  periods  covered.  Since  price  cuts  apply  not 
only  to  future  but  past  sales,  the  reluctance  of  sellers  to  reduce  prices 
is  correspondingly  increased. 

PRICE   LINES 

The  foregoing  pages  have  described  the  multiplicity  of  nonprice 
factors  which  can  be  varied  to  furnish  a  basis  for  competitive  rivalry 
and  the  variety  of  industries  in  which  they  appear.  It  is  important 
to  emphasize  that  the  presence  or  absence  of  price  competition  is  not 
of  itself  a  criterion  of  monopoly  or  collusion.  While  it  is  probably 
true  that  active  price  competition  is  infrequent  in  monopolistic 
markets,  it  is  also  possible  for  competitive  rivalry  to  center  largely 
or  exclusively  upon  nonprice  elements  even  in  highly  competitive 
industries. 

The  nature  of  the  commodity  may  be  such  as  to  make  price  com- 
parisons difficult  and  emphasis  upon  nonprice  factors  logical.  Where 
this  tendency  exists,  it  may  be  reinforced  by  the  development  of 
conventional  patterns  of  business  practice.  The  so-called  price  lines 
which  characterize  the  retail  and  wholesale  markets  for  a  fairly  wide 
variety  of  commodities  furnish  an  outstanding  example  of  such 
crystallization  of  business  custom. 

Price  lines  are  most  commonly  associated  with  the  apparel  market. 
In  the  case  of  women's  dresses,  for  example,  a  series  of  definite  whole- 
sale prices  has  become  established  by  the  accumulation  of  habit  and 
tradition.     These  are: 


$1.87>^  each 
2.25 

2.87/2  " 
3.75 
4.75 
6.75 
7.75 
8.75 


$10.75  each 
12.75  " 
14.75  " 
16.75  " 
19.75  " 
22.75  " 
29.75  " 
39.75  and  over 


Manufacturers  and  wholesale  buyers  of  dresses  have  come  to  accept 
these  lines  as  virtually  immutable,"  except  that  new  lines  may  be 
added  when  extreme  changes  in  cost  occur.  They  are  rarely,  if  ever, 
considered  subject  to  modification  by  bargaining.  In  planning  pro- 
duction, the  manufacturer  carefully  estimates  the  material  and  labor 
costs  which  will  be  required  to  produce  a  desired  model  and  then 
makes  such  modification  in  the  design  as  wiU  be  necessary  to  permit 
him  to  sell  the  product  at  one  of  these  accepted  fines.  The  com- 
petition between  two  manufacturers  producing,  say,  a  $6.75  dress 
will  center  not  upon  the  price,  but  upon  the  quality  of  materials,  the 
quafity  of  trimmings,  the  workmanship,  and  the  amount  of  style. 
The  efforts  of  the  buyer  similarly  will  be  concentrated  upon  obtaining 
the  maximum  value  at  a  given  price  and  not  upon  breaking  down  the 
price  line  itself. 

It  is  probable  that  even  rigidly  established  customs  of  this  sort 
may  be  somewhat  shaken  during  periods  of  severe  economic  stress  as, 
for  example,  during  the  buyers'  market  which  prevailed  during  the 
trough  of  the  depression.     Thus,  it  may  be  significant  that  the  mem- 

"  The  prices  listed  are  gross  prices  subject  to  standard  trade  and  cash  discounts. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


71 


bers  of  the  corset  and  brassiere  industry  deemed  it  advisable  to  stipu- 
late rigid  adherence  to  accepted  price  lines  as  a  code  provision  during 
N.  R.  A.     The  clause  in  question  follows:  ^* 

Wholesale  prices. — To  maiDtaih  established  trade  practice,  and  to  liroit  the 
multiplication  of  numbers,  but  without  any  attempt  at  price  fixing,  each  person 
being  free  to  determine  the  value  to  be  given  at  each  price,  the  following  shall  be 
the  wholesale  prices,  per  dozen,  for  sale  to  retailers  (except  chain  stores  selling 
up  to  one  dollar  ($1)  retail),  and  no  intermediate  prices  may  be  used: 


$2.00  doz. 
2.25 
3.25 
4.00 
4.25 
4.50 
6.00 
7.00 
8.00 


$8.50  doz. 

10.50 

12.00 

15.00 

16.50 

18.00 

21.00 

22.50 

24.00 


$27.00  doz. 
30.00 
33.00 
36.00 
42.00 
48.00 
54.00 
60.00 
66.00  and  up. 


Price  lines  in  the  wholesale  market  are  reflected  in  a  similar  though 
perhaps  slightly  less  invariable  practice  at  retail.  This  is  illustrated 
by  the  prices  reported  by  the  Retail  Price  Division  of  the  Bureau 
of  Labor  Statistics,  covering  the  quotations  of  representative  retailers 
32   cities.     For   example,    114   quotations   for  women's   medium 


m 


Price — Continued. 


$4.69. 

$5---, 
$5.50. 


Number  of 
guotatioTU 

....  1 

....  1 

.---  67 

....  2 


Total 114 


quality,  woven  elastic  girdles,  retailing  from  $2.95  to  $5.50,  showed 
the  following  distribution  as  of  June  15,  1938: 

Number  of 
Price:  quotations 

$2.95 - 4 

$2.98 2 

$3.39 1 

$3.50 32 

$3.59 1 

$3.95 2 

$3.98 1 

In  other  words,  99  of  the  1 14  price  quotations  were  concentrated  at 
2  figures — $3.50  and  $5.  Only  15  quotations,  or  13  percent  of  the 
total,  were  at  intermediate  figures. 

Similar  concentration  of  retail  prices  exists  for  many  other  apparel 
items.  For  example,  396  quotations  were  reported  for  women's 
hose  ranging  from  69  cents  to  $1.15  per  pair.  Of  these,  119  were  at 
79  cents  and  154  at  $1.  These  two  prices  alone  accounted  for  61 
percent  of  the  total. 

Although  apparel,  and  particularly  women's  apparel,  furnishes  the 
most  conspicuous  example  of  price  lining,  the  custom  is  by  no  means 
confined  to  these  fields.  Such  products  as  electric  refrigerators, 
vacuum  cleaners,  and  radios  also  show  a  distinct  tendency  toward  the 
establishment  of  a  limited  number  of  price  lines.  Table  21  in  chapter 
IV  (p.  162)  illustrates  the  effect  of  this  practice  in  the  case  of  refrig- 
erators. During  1939  all  major  producers  with  one  exception  quoted 
list  prices  which  were  almost  identical  for  each  size. 

The  retail  prices  of  vacuum  cleaners  are  usually  spaced  at  $10 
intervals  between  $39.95  and  $79.95.  It  is  apparently  the  opinion  of 
the  trade  that  intermediate  levels,  such  as  $42  or  $56,  would  meet 
with  customer  resistance  and  could  not  be  used.  Similar  variations 
apply  to  radios.'* 

"  National  Recovery  Administration,  Codes  of  Fair  Competition,  vol.  I,  p.  76,  Corset  and  Brassiers 
Industry,  sec.  9  (i). 
"  The  foregoing  and  additional  exanrples  of  price  lining  are  described  in  more  detail  In  appendix  II. 


247140 — 41— No.  1- 


y2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  influence  of  price  lines  upon  the  pattern  of  competition  has 
been  suggested  above.  In  both  the  wholesale  and  retail  markets  the 
buyer's  choice  is  confined  to  selecting  the  best  possible  value  at  a 
given  price  rather  than  to  comparing  prices  for  similar  products. 
The  force  of  this  generalization  is,  of  course,  limited  by  the  size  of 
the  interval  between  price  lines.  For  example,  the  consumer  may 
find  a  $3.50  girdle  as  satisfactoiy  as  one  ofl'ered  for  $5;  in  that  case 
price  becomes  the  paramount  consideration.  In  general,  however, 
there  is  an  appreciable  gradation  of  quality  comparable  to  that  of 
price;  in  other  words,  the  best  article  offered  at  $3.50  is  of  distinctly 
lower  grade  than  the  poorest  offered  at  $5.  Consequently,  though 
price  is  not  eliminated  as  a  consideration,  the  scope  of  price  com- 
petition is  limited. 

Frequently  another  consideration  rehiforces  the  emphasis  upon 
nonprice  factors.  Many  manufacturers,  particularly  in  the  field  of 
apparel,  concentrate  their  efforts  upon  not  more  than  one  or  two  price 
lines.  For  example,  a  women's  dress  manufacturer  may  be  spoken  of 
as  a  "$10.75  house"  or  a  "$14.75  house."  This  means  that  the  firm 
in  question  regularly  produces  garments  only  within  the  price  line 
specified.  Any  changes  in  costs  of  production  will  be  reflected  in 
changes  of  the  character  of  the  garment  and  not  in  modifications  of 
the  price.  For  such  one-price  houses  nonprice  channels  are  the 
only  form  of  competition  available. 

The  practice  of  price  lining  may  affect  market  patterns  not  only  for 
the  finished  products  sold  at  the  price  lines,  but  also  for  the  major 
raw  materials  entering  into  these  finished  products.  Thus  Mr.  S.  J. 
Kennedy  points  out  that  the  prevalence  of  price  lines  for  apparel  and 
for  piece  goods  is  reflected  in  the  gray  goods  market.  It  acts  to 
retard  the  responsiveness  of  finished  goods  prices  to  changes  in  tex- 
tile manufacturing  costs  and  means  that  the  advantage  of  certain 
savings  will  not  be  passed  on  to  the  consumer  promptly.  Thus  it 
introduces  distinct  rigidity  into  the  market: 

*  *  *  It  is  patent  that  seasonal  fluctuations  in  prices  of  gray  cloth,  even 
when  as  great  as  1  cent  per  yard,  do  not  always  reach  the  ultimate  consumer  in 
the  form  of  lower  prices.  If  the  given  cloth  were  converted  into  printed  percales 
to  be  sold  by  the  converter  at  14^  cents  per  yard  and  retailed  as  yard  goods  at 
25  cents  per  yard,  a  reduction  of  1  cent  per  yard  in  the  gray,  if  passed  on  by  the 
converter  to  the  retailer  would  have  no  effect  whatever  under  normal  conditions 
upon  the  price  paid  for  the  cloth  by  the  consumer.  It  is  not  a  large  enough  cut 
to  fit  the  cloth  into  a  19-cent  bracket,  which  is  the  next  lower  price  bracket  used 
generally  on  piece  goods  in  the  trade.  The  only  result  would  be  to  increase  the 
margin  to  the  retailer. 

Likewise,  if  the  cloth  went  into  the  hands  of  cutters-up  instead  of  their  selling 
the  garment  at  a  lower  price,  they  would  continue  the  sale  at  their  fixed  wholesale 
price,  and  at  best  might  put  on  more  or  better  trimmings  or  employ  a  more 
intricate  pattern  of  garment. 

In  other  words,  by  the  time  the  product  reaches  the  consumer,  price  changes  of 
a  temporary  or  minor  character  would  have  been  absorbed  bj'  the  channels  of 
distribution  so  that  there  is  no  certainty  that  such  savings  in  manufacturing  costs 
as  can  be  secured  from  the  u.se  of  more  efficient  macliinery  will  have  been  passed 
on  to  him.  The  increasing  price  inflexibility  of  our  distributing  system,  as  goods 
pass  from  primary  manufacturers  to  the  ultimate  retailers,  makes  it  increasingly 
unlikely  that  the  consumer  will  get  the  beneGt  of  these  savings  unless  they  are 
drastic  enough  to  move  the  product  out  of  one  price  bracket  into  a  lower  one. 

Conversely,  it  should  be  noted  that  increases  in  price  experience  similar  retarda- 
tion. The  same  increasing  price  inflexibility,  as  goods  pass  from  primary  manu- 
facturers to  retailers,  operates  to  prevent  a  price  rise  when  costs  are  increased. 
An  increase  of  1  cent  per  yard  in  gray  clotii  costs  would,  under  certain  conditions, 
be  absorbed  by  the  various  operators  out  of  their  gross  margins  before  the  goods 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


73 


reached  the  retail  counter.  Under  present  conditions  of  a  high  degree  of  organi- 
zation in  the  distributing  trades,  whereby  the  combined  buying  power  of  many 
individual  retail  outlets  is  applied  jointly  to  the  manufacturer,  the  latter  must 
absorb  more  than  his  share  of  this  reduction  in  price  spread.  In  other  words, 
his  own  prices  will  generally  be  less  flexible  than  his  costs'.  When  prices  reach  a 
certain  level,  he  will  be  unable  to  raise  his  price  further  and  still  get  any  business 
on  his  product. 

However,  before  such  a  level  is  reached  where  his  customers  are  no  longer  able 
to  use  the  product  for  existing  price  brackets,  the  primary  manufacturer  would 
probably  have  switched  to  a  lower  construction ;  for  example,  from  80  by  80  print 
cloth  to  68  by  72;  or  if  the  product  were  a  nonstandard  cloth,  he  would  have 
"cut"  the  construction  by  removing  a  few  ends  or  picks,  reducing  the  width,  using 
lighter  weight  yarns,  or  any  of  the  other  many  means  for  deteriorating  quality. 
On  the  other  hand,  if  the  price  rise  were  a  large  one,  enough  to  throw  the  cloth 
into  a  higher  retail  price  bracket,  then  the  manufacturer  could  get  a  higher  price 
and  maintain  his  profit  margin;  however,  the  volume  on  that  construction  would 
be  reduced  and  he  would  be  under  the  necessity  of  developing  a  cheaper  cloth  for 
the  lower  price  bracket  in  which  it  had  formerly  fitted. 

Put  in  another  way,  a  price  rise  due  to  external  factors  such  as  a  rise  in  cotton 
prices  or  a  manufacturers'  sales  tax,  would  put  the  manufacturer  under  the  neces- 
sity of  finding  a  way  to  make  the  cloth  at  lower  cost,  to  offset  the  increases  in 
these  other  elements  of  prime  cost.  Price  pressure  from  retail  distributors  would 
tend  to  prevent  the  manufacturer  from  raising  his  price  until  prices  were  practi- 
cally equal  to  his  direct  costs.  As  that  level  was  approached,  either  of  two  things 
would  happen:  (1)  The  cloth  might  be  forced  into  a  higher  retail  price  bracket — 
for  example,  from  29  cents  to  39  cents  per  yard  as  piece  goods  over  the  counter, 
or  from  a  $1  garment  to  $1.95 — in  which  case  the  volume  would  be  materially 
reduced,  and  a  lower  construction  would  be  developed  for  the  old  price  bracket; 
or  (2)  the  cloth  might  be  progressively  cheapened  by  "cutting"  the  construction 
as  the  price  rose,  and  be  kept  at  about  the  same  price  level. 


To  what  degree  such  "cuts"  in  construction  lower  the  actual  output  of  the  in- 
dustry or  give  consumers  less  for  their  money  is  not  a  problem  to  be  settled  here. 
In  large  measure  it  is  a  problem  in  home  economics,  and  is  to  be  decided  as  a  result 
of  research  concerning  relative  wearing  qualities  of  various  constructions,  and  the 
extent  to  which  retail  stores  give  actual  value  for  money  received. 

It  must  not  be  overlooked,  however,  that  this  flexibility  of  quality,  by  which 
manufacturers  are  able  to  adjust  to  price  fluctuations  without  lowering  real  manu- 
facturing costs,  permits  the  industry  to  meet  fluctuating  price  conditions  in  the 
cotton  market  with  a  minimum  of  internal  friction.  It  is  made  possible  only  by 
the  continued  lack  of  knowledge  on  the  part  of  the  consumers  (nonindustrial)  of 
what  actual  quahty  of  cloth  is.^" 

For  some  products,  price  lines  are  maintained  by  adjusting  quantity 
rather  than  quality  to  changing  conditions.  For  example,  the  retail 
price  of  bar  chocolate  is  usually  either  5  or  10  cents.  The  disinclina- 
tion of  many  customers  to  bother  with  odd  pennies  is  undoubtedly  one 
of  the  causes  for  the  crystallization  of  this  custom.  Changes  in  the 
size  of  the  bar  offered  by  a  leading  producer  follow. 


Table  3. — Changes  in  size 

of  chocolate  bars 

Date  of  change 

Net  weight  per  bar 

Plain 

Almond 

5  cents 
retail 

10  cents 
retail 

5  cents 
retail 

10  cents 
retail 

Jan.  I,  1926 

\% 
2 

2'^ 

2?^ 

4 

4 

35^ 

1 

2 

Apr.  1,  1930 

2H 

Oct.  10,  1931 

3Ji 

Sept.  2,  1932 

3 

Nov.  4,  1032 

3 

'  Stephen  Jay  Kennedy,  Profits  and  Losses  in  Textiles,  pp.  168-170. 


•jf^  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Similarly,  it  is  understood  that  the  contents  of  packaged  goods  sold 
by  limited  price  variety  stores  are  changed  from  time  to  time  in  order 
that  the  conventional  5-cent,  10-cent,  and  25-cent  lines  may  be  rigidly 
maintained. 

Bread  affords  a  particularly  striking  illustration  of  the  way  in  which 
a  price  line  can  be  maintained  by  varying  quantity.  A  total  of  1,132 
retail  price  quotations  for  bread  from  stores  located  throughout  the 
country  were  reported  to  the  Retail  Price  Division  of  the  Bureau  of 
Labor  Statistics  as  of  February  1939.  Of  these  1,132  quotations, 
808  or  71  percent  were  at  10  cents.  In  8  of  the  9  major  geographic 
census  areas,  the  10-cent  loaf  accounted  for  more  than  50  percent  of 
the  total  nimiber  of  quotations.  In  contrast  to  this  uniformity  of 
price,  the  size  of  the  loaves  offered  for  10  cents  varied  from  16  ounces 
to  24  ounces. 

Price  lining  is  also  characteristic  of  many  noncommodity  prices. 
Examples  may  be  drawn  from  common  experience.  Thus,  in  many 
localities,  the  charge  for  dry  cleaning  a  suit  of  clothes  is  apt  to  be  either 
75  cents  or  39  cents;  intermediate  prices  are  unusual.  The  usual 
price  for  haircuts  is  either  35  cents  or  50  cents.  Frequently  the  price 
of  services  is  related  to  the  size  of  convenient  monetary  units  (e.  g'., 
5  cents  or  10  cents)  as  in  the  case  of  shoeshines  or  a  cup  of  coffee  in 
ii  restaurant. 

The  foregoing  exam^plcs  show  clearly  that  the  practice  of  price 
lining  definitely  influences  the  focus  of  competition.  It  does  not, 
however,  eliminate  price  competition  entirely,  but  rather  restricts 
its  scope. 

In  general,  price  lines  are  more  rigidly  adhered  to  in  the  wholesale 
than  in  the  retail  markets.  Yet,  even  in  wholesale  markets,  prices 
are  shaded  from  time  to  time.  In  general  this  is  done  by  modifying 
one  of  the  collateral  terms  of  sale.  The  most  important  of  these  is 
the  so-called  cash  discount.  In  most  apparel  lines,  for  example,  it  is  a 
custom  to  allow  a  discount  of  8  percent,  10  days  E.  O.  M.^'  In 
reality,  as  the  size  of  the  discount  indicates,  this  is  a  combination 
trade  discount  and  cash  discount.  It  constitutes  an  important  modi- 
fication of  the  nominal  wholesale  price  quotation.  There  is  some 
evidence  that  it  is  not  adhered  to  quite  as  rigidly  as  the  nominal  price 
line  itself.  It  is  commonly  believed  that  price  concessions  are  some- 
times granted,  particularly  to  very  large  buyers,  by  increasing  this 
discount,  usually  to  10  percent.  Indirect  price  concessions  may  also 
be  granted  by  the  use  of  other  devices  as,  for  example,  by  absorbing 
freight  on  certain  shipment'^. 

In  general,  however,  price  variations  of  this  kind  in  the  wholesale 
market  are  comparatively  minor.  In  the  retail  market,  on  the  other 
hand,  somewhat  greater  variations  occur.  Thus  the  retail  prices 
listed  above  (p.  71)  reveal  a  material  number  of  exceptions  to  the 
established  price  lines.  Presumably  these  reflect  variations  in  the 
pricing  policy  of  different  retail  outlets.  Retailers  whose  operating 
costs  are  lower  than  the  average  may  operate  at  lower  than  normal 
mark-ups  and  thereby  deviate  from  the  established  lines. 

These  cases  are  aU,  however,  exceptions  to  the  general  rule. 
Broadly  speaking,   the  practice  of  price  lining  necessarily  diverts 

"  I.  p.,  the  discount  applies  if  ;>■  -ment  Is  made  not  later  than  ttio  10th  day  of  the  month  following  that 
during  which  the  sale  was  made. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  75 

competition  into  nonprice  channels.  The  efforts  of  the  producer  and 
the  choice  of  the  consumer  both  must  accept  prices  as  constant  and 
center  upon  such  factors  as  quahty  as  the  significant  variables. 

It  should  again  be  emphasized  that  this  conventional  restriction 
of  price  competition  is  in  no  sense  associated  with  concentration  or 
with  any  manifestations  of  monopoly  power.  Most  of  the  industries 
in  which  price  lining  is  prevalent  are  composed  largely  of  small  enter- 
prise and  are  by  almost  any  criterion  highly  competitive.  The 
highly  diversified  nature  of  the  product  makes  emphasis  upon  non- 
price  factors  almost  inevitable. 

There  is  no  evidence  that  the  practice  of  price  lining,  as  such,  is 
notably  ineflBcient  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  consumer  or  the 
economy.  It  apparently  introduces  certain  undesirable  rigidities  in 
the  market  for  apparel  and  other  consumers'  goods  which,  in  times  of 
rapidly  changing  costs,  hamper  market  adjustments.  However, 
these  rigidities  do  not  appear  to  be  sufficiently  serious  to  create  major 
issues  of  public  policy.  Price  lining,  therefore,  affords  an  illustration 
of  the  manner  in  which  factors  inherent  in  the  market  more  or  less 
naturaUy  lead  to  emphasis  upon  nonprice  elements  as  the  focus  of 
business  rivalry  without  materially  affecting  the  costs  of  production 
or  distribution  or  the  efficiency  with  which  consumers'  wants  are 
satisfied. 

ADVERTISING,    BRANDS,    AND    TRADE-MARKS 

The  practice  of  price  lining  does  not  of  itself  introduce  any  new 
elements  into  the  transaction.  Given  a  situation  in  which  the 
product  of  rival  sellers  necessarily  differs  in  quality  and  style,  there 
has  merely  been  a  decision  to  concentrate  com^petitive  effort  upon 
these  elements  and  to  accept  price  as  constant.  This  procedure 
represents  a  simple  choice  of  emphasis  between  elements  which  were 
in  any  event  present,  and  does  not  of  itself  involve  any  major  changes 
in  the  cost  of  manufacturing  or  distribution. 

In  contrast,  increasing  use  of  advertising,  brands,  and  trade-marks 
has  far  broader  implications.  It  represents  the  introduction  of  new 
elements  into  the  transaction;  elements  which  are  not  necessarily  in- 
herent in  the  nature  of  the  commodities  offered  for  sale,  and  it  has 
far-reaching  effects  upon  the  functioning  of  the  economy. 

In  one  sense,  the  purpose  of  advertising  is  to  disseminate  informa- 
tion as  to  those  quality  features  in  which  the  prospective  purchaser 
might  be  interested,  while  brands  and  trade-marks  furnish  a  ready 
means  for  identifying  the  merchandise  in  question.  To  an  extent, 
therefore,  advertising  and  branding  may  be  considered  a  phase  of 
the  tactics  involved  in  competition  based  upon  quality. 

However,  advertising  is  rarely,  if  ever,  content  with  presenting  a 
dispassionate,  factual  description  of  the  quality  or  merits  of  an 
article;  nor  is  the  use  of  a  brand  merely  a. device  to  permit  the  ready 
identification  of  a  product  having  certain  specific  qualities. 

Essentially  a  brand  or  trade-mark  is  a  device  used  by  a  seller  to 
distinguish  his  product  from  similar  competing  articles.  Advertising 
is  used  to  persuade  the  prospective  purchaser  that  the  product  has 
certain  desirable  characteristics  which  are  unique  or  which  it  possesses 
in  greater  measure  than  rival  merchandise.  If  this  effort  is  success- 
ful, a  demand  is  created  for  the  article  associated  with  its  brand  or 


yg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

trade-mark,  and  purchasers  will  specify  such  a  brand  or  trade-mark 
in  their  buying.  Thereby  two  related  ends  may  be  accomplished. 
The  establishment  of  consumer  preference  for  a  specific  brand  yields 
its  owner  a  certain  assured  sales  volume.  At  the  same  time  the 
product  for  which  preference  has  been  established  is  shielded  to  a 
greater  or  lesser  extent  from  the  impact  of  direct  price  competition. 

The  effectiveness  with  which  the  use  of  trade-marks  and  brand 
names  can  insulate  a  product  against  direct  price  competition  with 
similar  articles  made  by  others  varies  materially  for  different  kinds 
of  goods.  Probably  the  most  important  determining  factor,  although 
it  is  but  one  of  many,  is  the  relative  ease  or  difficulty  which  the  con- 
sumer encounters  in  making  comparisons  between  the  actual  intrinsic 
merits  of  rival  merchandise.  In  those  fields  in  which  such  compari- 
sons are  relatively  simple,  or  in  markets  where  buyers  are  wel!  equipped 
technically,  there  is  a  pronounced  tendency  to  switch  to  competing 
brands  as  soon  as  material  price  differences  appear.  However,  where 
for  one  or  another  reason  the  consumer  is  unable  to  compare  rival 
products  intelligently,  the  effective  use  of  brands  or  trade-marks 
frequently  permits  very  wide  price  differences  to  be  maintained  be- 
tween virtually  identical  products.  In  such  fields  it  is  essential  to 
appraise  brand  significance  in  interpreting  price  behavior. 

Trained  buyers — industrial,  institutional,  or  governmental — are 
often  well  equipped  to  compare  competing  products  on  their  merits. 
Sometimes,  as  in  the  case  of  Government  agencies,  their  judgment  is 
aided  by  access  to  the  services  of  well-equipped  laboratories.  In 
cases  of  this  sort,  the  effectiveness  of  brands  is  limited.  The  buyer 
is  unlikely  to  accept  advertising  representations  without  investigation, 
particularly  if  appreciable  price  differences  appear  between  similar 
products  bearing  different  brands. ^^ 

The  average  household  consumer  is  in  a  totally  different  position. 
He  lacks  the  training,  the  facilities,  and  the  time  required  for  tech- 
nical comparisons  of  the  merits  of  competing  merchandise.  Even 
in  fields  in  which  commodity  standards  or  methods  of  rating  exist, 
these  are  often  inadequate  or  misleading.  Thus  Mr.  L.  R.  Walker, 
testifying  before  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee, 
asserted  that  technological  changes  had  made  the  prevailing  system  of 
measuring  the  capacity  of  warm-air  furnaces  for  homes  largely  useless 
as  a  guide  to  their  heating  capacity,  but  that  many  members  of  the 
industry  opposed  the  introduction  of  more  meaningful  standards. 
According  to  Mr.  Walker: 

I  would  say  this:  that  the  standard  that  the  consumer  has  been  taught  to  use 
is  no  measure  whatever  of  the  rating  of  the  product  he  gets.  In  other  words, 
because  the  industry  for  many  years  all  made  a  similar  product  they  used  one 
measure.  Now,  as  we  have  learned  to  improve  that  product,  they  are  still  using 
that  same  measure  and  it  doesn't  at  all  typify  the  output  of  that  product.  More 
than  half  of  the  industry  is  still  making  the  old  product  and  opposes  anything 
that  changes  that  standard.^* 

The  interest  of  the  consumer  in  obtaining  more  adequate  informa- 
tion regarding  the  character  of  commodities  on  the  market  has 
resulted  in  the  establishment  of  a  number  of  organizations  whose 
purpose  is  to  supply  the  consumer  with  technical  guides  in  his  pur- 
chasing.    However,  there  are  limits  to  the  effectiveness  with  which 

»  See  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  Hearings,  Part  8,  pp.  3440-3452. 
Mlbid.,  p.  3422. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


77 


such  private  organizations  can  perform  this  function.  Moreover,  in 
the  case  of  several  of  these  organizations,  there  even  seems  to  be  some 
question  as  to  the  good  faith  of  their  activities. ^^  Consequently,  the 
average  consumer  is  forced  to  a  large  extent  to  rely  upon  advertising 
claims  and  to  base  his  buying  upon  brand  names  and  trade-marks. 

In  grocery  products,  for  example,  a  distinction  must  be  drawn  be- 
tween such  relatively  standard  commodities  as  sugar  or  rice,  and  those 
in  which  there  are  wide  variations  of  quality,  flavor,  and  contents, 
such  as  canned  peas  or  coffee.  Even  the  former  may  be  and  often  are 
purchased  by  brand,  but  as  soon  as  any  material  price  differences 
appear  the  average  housewife  is  almost  certain  to  switch  to  a  cheaper 
variety.  In  the  case  of  the  latter  products,  however,  even  material 
price  differences  may  not  suffice  to  induce  her  to  change  her  habits  of 
purchasing.  Taste  is  so  subjective  an  element  that  comparisons 
between  different  brands  of,  say,  canned  goods  are  inevitably  difficult. 
Moreover,  choice  is  complicated  by  the  general  refusal  of  packers  to 
adopt  grade  labeling  for  canned  products,  as  well  as  by  the  multi- 
plicity of  can  sizes  which  hampers  any  attempt  to  match  prices  on  a 
uniform  basis.^^ 


Table  4. — Prices  and  quality  grades  for  specified  brands  of  canned  foods 
GREEN  AND  WAX  BEANS 


Brand 

Price  per 
pound 

Quality 
grade 

Brand 

Price  per 
pound 

Quality 
grade 

A.  &  P 

$0.13 
.14 
.19 

.08 

;08 
.11 
.15 

A 
B 

A 

C 
C 

c 

B 

lona 

Premier  (wax). 

Shrivers    -    -           -  .- 

$0.11 
.16 
.13 
f       .11 
1        .13 
.25 
.18 
.17 

C 

Asco 

B 

Blue  Label 

B 

Blue  Ridge 

Stokely                 .  . 

C 

Crown  or  Maryland     

Sweetheart 

Torsch's 

White  Rose  (wax) 

A 

Farmdale 

Fort 

C 
B 

BARTLETT  PEARS 


Approval.. 

Asco 

Blue  Label 
D.  O.  S  .. 
Del  Monte 
De  Mand. 

Hunt 

lona 


$0.10 

B 

.11 

A 

.16 

B 

.18 

C 

.13 

B 

.15 

C 

.14 

A 

.10 

C 

Libby 

Lyric 

Mission 

Premier 

Ray  Crest... 

S.  &.  W 

White  Rose. 


TOMATO  JUICE 


Alice 

Ann  Page 

Approval 

Asco 

Beech-Nut 

Campbell 

College  Inn._ 

Blackwell  &  Crosse 
Heinz's 


$0,066 

1  A  (86) 

.096 

A  (94) 

.083 

D  (C5) 

.080 

A  (90) 

.118 

A  (90) 

.096 

A  (92) 

.C99 

A  (90) 

.108 

C  (84) 

.106 

A  (94) 

Le  Grande. 

Libby. 

Phillips 

Ritter 

Scott 

Stokely 

Webster 

Welch 

White  Rose 


$0. 101 
.096 
.076 
.075 
.057 
.087 
.072 
.15 
.118 


C  (78) 
A  (89) 
C(78) 
A  (87) 
A  (92) 
A  (93) 
A  (96) 
A  (94"/ 
C  (82) 


'  Number  in  parentheses  is  the  numerical  grade. 

Source:  Hearing  before  the  Committee  on  Coinage,  Weights,  and  Measures,  House  of  Representatives, 
on  H.  R.  6964,  Standard  Metal  Container  Act  of  1937,  Mar.  15  and  18,  1938,  pp.  20-21. 

»  The  Federal  Trade  Commission  is  at  present  (Spring,  1940)  proceeding  against  two  organizations 
which  purport  to  furnish  the  consumer  with  technical  buying  information.  See  complaints  of  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission  in  the  matter  of  Albert  Lane,  an  individual,  trading  as  Consumers'  Bureau  of  Stand- 
ard?, Docket  Xo.  3718,  and  in  the  matter  of  Hearst  Magazines,  Inc.,  Docket  No.  3872. 

"  Sec  Temporary  National  Econongic  Committee  Hearings,  Part  8,  pp.  3346-3355. 


yg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Some  of  the  consequences  of  this  situation  are  reflected  in  table  4, 
which  is  based  upon  data  presented  at  recent  congressional  hearings. 
The  price  per  pound  of  different  brands  of  Bartlett  pears,  tomato 
juice,  and  green  and  wax  beans,  is  compared.  The  quality  grades 
based  upon  the  standards  of  the  Bureau  of  Agricultural  Economics 
are  also  indicated.  It  is  apparent  that  there  is  no  significant  corre- 
lation between  price  and  quality.  Thus,  one  brand  of  grade  A  beans 
costs  approximately  twice  as  much  per  pound  as  another  brand  meeting 
the  same  specifications.  Products  of  lower  grade  sold  for  more  than 
those  of  higher  grade. 

An  informal  questionnaire  recently  circulated  among  a  small  group 
of  consumers  in  Washington  and  Boston,  by  the  members  of  the  Tem- 
porary National  Economic  Committee  staff,  gives  some  indication  of 
the  extent  to  which  brand  preference  prevails  in  the  grocery  market. 
This  questionnaire  comprised  a  list  of  60  common  prepared  foods.^^ 
Consumers  were  asked  to  specify  the  degree  to  which  their  purchasing 
was  affected  by  brand  preferences  in  accordance  with  the  following 
instructions: 

Mark  the  item  "a"  if,  in  buying,  you  simply  ask  for  it  by  its  general  name 
without  giving  attention  to  its  brand  or  trade-mark.  (E.  g.,  "Give  me  a  loaf  of 
bread.")  ,, 

Mark  the  item  "b"  if  you  usually  ask  for  a  specific  brand  and  buy  it  if  it  is 
no  more  expensive  than  competing  brands  but  are  still  usually  willing  to  accept 
substitutes  for  trial  or  to  save  a  cent  or  two. 

Mark  the  item  "c"  if  you  ask  for  it  by  brand  name  and  insist  upon  it,  despite 
small  differences  in  price,  but  are  nevertheless  willing  to  experiment  with  other 
brands  and  to  shift  if  price  differences  become  material. 

Mark -the  item  "d"  if  you  insist  upon  a  specific  brand  despite  material  price 
differences  between  it  and  competing  brands  and  if  you  are  not,  generally  speaking, 
willing  to  experiment  with  other  brands. 

Mark  the  item  "x"  if  you  do  not  use  it,  or  if  your  experience  with  it  has  been 
too  meager  to  furnish  a  basis  for  judgment. 

NOTES 

(1)  By  price  difference  is  meant,  not  only  differences  in  the  price  itself  but  ako 
differences  in  other  material  factors  such  as  quality,  grade,  size  of  can,  attractive 
premiums,  and  the  like, 

(2)  The  habit  of  buying  in  a  specific  store  because  you  like  the  products  handled 
there  is  not,  for  this  purpose,  to  be  considered  equivalent  to  buying  by  brand. 
For  example,  if  you  like  the  butter  handled  by  a  certain  grocery  and  regularly  buy 
it  there,  but  if  it  is  sold  loose  or  if  you  are  unaware  of  its  brand  name,  you  are 
not  buying  by  brand.  On  the  other  hand,  if  you  go  to  that  store  because  it 
happens  to  carry,  say,  Blue  Valley  Butter,  you  are  buying  by  brand. 

The  results  are  summarized  in  table  5.  Particular  attention  is 
directed  to  the  frequency  with  which  consumers  indicated  that  they 
would  insist  upon  their  favorite  brand  despite  material  difference  s  in 

Erice.  Thus,  in  the  case  of  such  products  as  tea,  canned  salmon, 
aked  beans,  and  flour,  ipore  than  a -third  of  those  answering  the 
question  indicated  that  they  would  insist  upon  their  favorite  brand 
regardless  of  price  and  another  third  would  change  only  if  the  price 
inducement  were  material. 

»  The  lirt  was  selected  from  those  prepared  foods  whose  prices  are  reported  in  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Sta- 
tlsncs  wholesale  price  Index.    This  was  done  to  permit  comparisons  of  price  behavior. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Table  5. — Extent  of  consumer  brand  preference  for  prepared  foods 


79 


Name  of  commodity 


Dried  apples 

Powdered  milk , 

Pretzels 

Dried  peaches 

Cored  beef 

Dried  apricots 

Dried  currants 

Black  pepper , 

Rice.- , 

Corn  meal 

Granulated  sugar 

Fresh  meat 

Dressed  poultry 

Cornstarch 

Vinegar , 

Hominy  grits 

Peanut  butter 

American  cheese 

Sweet  crackers 

Olive  oil - 

Grape  jam 

Canned  apples 

Dried  prunes 

Lard 

Oleo  oil - 

Canned  cherries 

Canned  string  beans. 

Soda  water 

Soda  crackers 

Macaroni- 

Canned  apricots 

Canned  pears , 

Canned  spinach 

Canned  tomatoes 

Cured  ham 

Oleomargarine 

Cendensed  milk 

Corn  flakes 

Canned  peaches 

Canned  pineapple... 

Dried  raisins 

Canned  corn 

Salt.- 

Molasses 

Butter 

Wheat  cereal 

Evaporated  milk 

White  bread 

Rolled  oats 

Canned  peas 

Bacon 

Ginger  ale 

Grape  juice 

Cocoa 

Canned  asparagus... 

Family  flour 

Canned  baked  beans 

Tomato  soup 

Canned  salmon. 

Tea.... 


Total  re- 
porting 


Number  of  consumers  who  purchased — 


Without  re 
gard  for 
brand  or 

trade-mark 


With  regard  to  brand  or  trade-mark 


Total 


By  brand  if 

not  higher 

in  price 


By  brand 
unless  there 
was  a  very 
marked 
price  dif- 
ferential 


By  brand 

regardless 

of  price 


Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


gQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

In  the  field  of  apparel,  price  comparisons  are  in  some  ways  more 
difficult  than  in  that  of  groceries.  To  the  average  consumer,  such 
matters  as  thread  count  or  tensile  strength  are  mysteries.^^  Few 
buyers  will  examine  a  shirt  to  see  how  many  stitches  there  are  per 
inch.  Many  do  not  even  know  that  such  terms  as  "satin"  or  "crepe" 
or  "velvet"  refer  to  weave  and  not  to  fiber  content.  Consequently, 
there  is  often  a  substantial  difference  in  prices  between  apparel  sold 
under  a  well-known  label  and  similar  more  obscure  brands.  For 
example,  according  to  data  compiled  by  the  Retail  Price  Division  of 
the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics,  the  average  price  of  one  nationally 
advertised  brand  of  men's  business  shirts  during  December  1937  was 
$2,  while  the  average  for  alh  other  brands  meeting  the  same  general 
set  of  specifications  was  $1.61. 

Frequently,  apparel  manufacturers  sell  identical  products  under 
several  dift'erent  brands,  one  of  which  may  bear  their  own  nationally 
advertised  label,  while  the  others  bear  distributors'  labels.  Generally 
the  product  sold  under  the  manufacturer's  label  commands  a  sub- 
stantial premium  both  in  retail  and  wholesale  markets,  over  that 
bearing  the  distributor's  label.  In  the  case  of  hosiery,  for  example, 
according  to  the  Knit  Goods  Weekly, ^^  the  difference  between  na- 
tionally advertised  and  private  label  merchandise  is  normally  75  cents 
per  dozen.  Prior  to  1938  the  difference  had  been  $1.25  per  dozen. 
Since  the  product  is  identical,  the  differential  simply  represents  the 
value  of  the  brand. 

Similar  situations  exist  in  many  other  lines.  A  recent  investigation 
by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  showed  that  the  Goodyear  Tire  & 
Rubber  Co.  was  selling  tires  to  Sears,  Roebuck  &  Co.  under  the  brand 
"All  State"  which  were  of  the  same  quality  as  those  marketed  by  the 
Goodyear  Co.  under  its  own  "All  Weather"  brand.  The  difierence 
in  wholesale  prices  between  these  two  brands  during  the  period  from 
1927  to  1933  varied  between  29  and  40  percent.  On  the  retail  market 
the  "All  State"  brand  was  generally  sold  at  prices  between  20  and  25 
percent  below  the  price  of  the  "All  Weather"  brand. ^^ 

In  another  case  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  found  that  the  Ameri- 
can Featherbed  &  Pillow  Co.  marketed  their  products  under  the  five 
brand  names  "Princess,"  "Progress,"  "Washington,"  "Puritan,"  and 
"Ideal."  In  its  advertising  the  manufacturer  represented  that  these 
products  were  of  different  grades  in  the  order  named,  and  correspond- 
ingly different  prices  were  charged  for  each.  The  Commission  found, 
however,  that  all  these  five  brands  were  of  the  same  quality,  and  that 
the  material  price  differential  between  the  "Princess"  and  the  "Ideal" 
brand  reflected  a  difference  in  the  label  only.^*^ 

Similarly,  it  is  understood  that  there  has  been  a  difference  of  $50 
in  retail  price  between  virtually  identical  refrigerators  sold  under  the 
manufacturer's  label  and  that  of  a  large  distributor. 

Probably  the  outstanding  example  of  the  degree  to  which  trade- 
niarks  and  brand  names  can  grant  immunity  from  price  competition 
is  furnished  by  the  drug  and  cosmetic  trade."^  In  this  field  the  aver- 
age consumer  is  dealing  with  something  which  is  to  him  utterly  mys- 
terious.    Moreover,  it  is  a  field  in  which  experiment  is  not  only  diflfi- 

"  See  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  nearings,  Part  8,  pp.  3287-3308. 
"  Knit  Goods  Weekly,  January  3,  1938,  p.  8. 
"  Federal  Trade  Commission,  Docket  No.  2110. 
w  Federal  Trade  Commission,  Docket  No.  1129. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


81 


cult  but  may  be  dangerous.  Few  consumers  have  any  possible  way 
of  appraising  the  merits  of  rival  drugs.  They  know  nothing  of  chemi- 
cal formulas.  Few  are  familiar  with  the  significance  of  the  specifica- 
tions of  the  United  States  Pharmacopoeia.  They  may  be  guided  by 
the  advice  of  their  physicians  or  druggists,  or  perhaps  by  advertising 
claims  as  to  the  virtues  of  various  preparations. 

As  a  result,  very  w^ide  price  differences  are  encountered  between 
products  of  virtually  identical  chemical  composition.  Table  6  com- 
pares the  wholesale  prices  of  identical  preparations  sold  under  pro- 
prietary and  nonproprietary  names.  On  the  entire  list  the  aggregate 
cost  of  one  ounce  of  each  of  these  products  sold  under  their  nationally 
advertised  labels,  is  $28.95,  while  when  marketed  under  their  chemi- 
cal names  the  price  is  only  $4.59.  Presumably,  retail  prices  show  a 
similar  spread.  Consequently,  the  bulk  of  the  price  paid  by  the  re- 
tailer, and  probably  by  the  consumer,  represents  the  value  of  the 
brand.  The  saving  for  purchases  under  the  nonproprietary  name 
averaged  76  percent.^^ 

Table  %.— Comparison  of  wholesale  prices  of  identical  sxibstances  sold  under  pro- 
prietary and  nonproprietary  names 

[Net  prices  to  retailers  July  1938] 


Brand  name 


Phenatetin 

Bayer  Aspirin... 

Veronal 

Veronal  Sodium-. 

Atophan 

Duotal-Withrop. 

UrotroT^in 

Luminal 

Luminal  Sodium 
Irinol-Withrop  . 
Aristol-Withrop. 

Total 


Price  per 
ounce 


$0.  03 
.75 
3.00 
3.00 
2.75 
1.07 
.25 
6.90 
6.90 
1.90 
1.80 


28.95 


Chemical  name 


Acetphentidin 

Acetylsalicylic  acid.... 
Barbital 

Barbital  sodium 

Anchophen,  _ 

Guaiacol  carbonate 

Mothenamine 

Phenobarhital 

Phenobarbital  sodium 
Sulphonethylmethane 
Thymol-iodide 

Total 


Price  per 
ounce 


$0.21 
.13 
.56 
.62 
.38 
.29 
.13 
.57 
.57 
.70 
.43 


4.59 


Saving  under 
chemical  name 


Amount     Percent 


$0.42 

.62 

2.44 

2.38 

2.37 

.78 

.12 

6.33 

6.33 

1.20 

1.37 


24.36 


66.7 
82.7 
81.3 
79.3 
86.2 
72.9 
48.0 
91.7 
91.7 
63.2 
76.1 


176.3 


>  Average,  unweighted. 

Source:  Price  data  obtained  from  Blue  Price  List  Section,  published  by  American  Druggist,  July  193?. 


The  high  degree  of  immunity  from  direct  price  competition  which 
the  owner  of  branded  drugs,  toiletries,  or  cosmetics,  enjoys  is  often 
reflected  in  a  very  v/ide  spread  between  the  price  of  his  product  and 
the  cost  of  its  ingredients.^^  This  is  particularly  true,  of  course,  in 
the  case  of  nonstandard  proprietary  items  of  whose  composition  the 
consumer  is  generally  ignorant. 

Num.erous  efforts  have  been  made  to  compare  the  retail  prices  of 
some  of  these  products  with  the  physical  cost  of  their  ingredients. 
Among  the  agencies  which  have  conducted  such  work  are  the  Ameri- 
can Medical  Association  and  the  Bureau  of  Health  of  the  State  of 
Maine.     A  summary  of  some  of  these  data  is  presented  in  table  7. 

The  items  included  in  this  table  are  in  fields  which  are,  in  the  broad 
sense,  highly  competitive.     Consequently  the  very  wide  spreads  and 

"  For  other  examples  of  wide  price  spreads  between  trade-marked  and  unbranded  produets~see  Tempo- 
rary National  Economic  Committee  Hearings,  Part  8,  pp.  3444-3452,  and  also  Part  HI  of  this  voii  me,  infra, 
pp.  398-69. 

M  Of  course  this  spread  is  by  no  means  all  profit.  Much  of  it  represents  the  cost  of  advertising  and 
packaging. 


82 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


lack  of  any  consistent  relationship  between  ingredient  costs  and  prices 
clearly  attest  the  importance  of  branding  as  an  aspect  of  nonprice 
competition.  At  the  same  time  they  demonstrate  the  futility  of  at- 
tempting to  base  price  statistics  or  indexes  upon  physical  specifica- 
tions for  products  of  this  kind.  The  significance  of  the  brand  far 
transcends  that  of  the  constituents  of  the  product  or  any  conceivable 
criterion  of  performance. 

So  far,  the  discussion  has  been  concerned  with  the  effect  of  brands 
upon  the  price  level  prevailing  at  any  instant.  In  addition,  however, 
brands  may  exert  a  very  definite  effect  upon  the  way  in  which  prices 
behave  during  a  period  of  time. 

Table  7. — Comparison  of  retail  prices  of  drugs,  cosmetics,  and  foods,  with  the  costs 

of  their  ingredients 


Product  name 

Advertised  u.se 

Quantity 

Cost  of  ingredients 

Retail  price 

under  brand 

name 

Wholesale 

Retail 

Proprietary  medicines: 

Cure  for  TB  and  ul- 
cers of  stomach. 

Ulcers  of  stomach,  hy- 
peracidity,   general 
gastric  distress. 

Phenobarbital     and 
baking-soda  tablets. 

$0.50 

$7.00. 

pound.' 
Currier's  Tablets ' 

100  tablets-.      .  - 

3  $1.85 

'.98 
.02 

$5.00. 

Renesol  *.. 

65  capsules 

$4.50. 

Electrovita '.- 

1  gallon 

$2.00. 

Mouthwashes:     Lister- 

Few  cents. - 
$0.10 

About  $1.00. 

ine.' 
Dental    remedy:     Ora- 

Dental  remedy 

$2.00. 

Noid.' 
Reducing  agent: 

Oermania    Herb 

Per  package. 

Per  package 

."i  niincps 

$0.15  

$1.50. 

Tea.8 
Lesser ' 

Bathing  salts 

Few  cents.. 
Few  cents.. 
About     40 

cents. 
2  cents  to  3 

cents. 
$0.65. 

$1.00. 

Min-amin  " 

Vitamin  food 

$1.00. 

Pomay  Rx  " 

Stardom's       Holly- 
Diet.n 

Salve --- 

Reducing  food 

8  ounces    

$10.00. 

Package    .    .    .. 

$1  to  $2. 

4  bottles  of  differ- 
ent substances. 

4.708  ounces 

$5.00. 

Downing's  Cure." 
Cosmetics: 

Coty's     Dusting 

Powder.'* 
Coty's    Face    Pow- 

.157 
.120 
.338 
.466 

.066 

.220 

.160 

.094 
.118 
.100 
.098 

.m 

.174 

$0.75. 

1  SIR  oiincps 

$0.75. 

der.u 
Elizabeth        Arden 

6.345  ounces 

$3.00. 

Face  Powder." 
Elizabeth        Arden 

11.244  ounces 

$3.00. 

Dusting    Powder 
Venetian." 
Harriett     Hubbard 

2.262  ounces  .  . 

$0.60. 

Ayer    Face    Pow- 
der." 
Harriett     Hubbard 

10.170  ounces 

$1.65. 

Ayer  Ayeristocrat 
Bath  Powder." 
Daggett  and  Rams- 

4.883  ounces 

$0.85. 

dell  Dusting  Pow- 
der." 
Daggett  and  Rams- 

2.934  min(y>B 

$0.85. 

dell  Face  Powder." 
Max    Factor    Face 

4.684  ounces    - 

$0.76. 

Powder." 
Helena   Rubonstein 

2.644  ounces 

$1.00. 

Faee  Powder." 
Bourjois  Sales  Corp. 

3.332  ounces    . 

$0.60. 

Poudre  Java." 
Evening    in    Paris 

6.020  ounces 

$1.10. 

Bath         Dusting 
Powder.*" 
Evening    in     Paris 

$1.10 

Face  Powder  with 
Perfume." 

See  footnoteB  at  end  of  table. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


83 


Table  7. —  Comparison  of  retail  prices  of  drugs,  cosmetics,  and  foods,  with  the  costs 
of  their  ingredients — Continued 


Product  name 

Advertised  use 

Quantity 

Cost  of  ingredients 

Retail  price 

under  brand 

name 

Wholesale 

Retail 

Cosmetics— Continued . 
Richard    Hudnut 

2.479  ounces 

$0. 065 

.077 

.197 

.140 

.061 

.037 
.082 

.143 
.038 

.024 
.737 
.031 
.071 
.088 

.061 
.087 
.190 

.268 
.252 
.053 
.082 

.100 
.200 

.140 

$0.55. 

Face  Powder  Mar- 
velous." 

1.872  ounces 

$1.00. 

der.23 
Luzier's     Cleansing 

Cream." 
Luzier's     Lu     Mar 

5.700  ounces.  

$2.50. 

1.802  ounce... 

$3.00. 

Massage  Cream. 2* 

2.109  ounces.- 

$1.00. 

Cream." 
Coty  Rouge  Refill  ». 
Max     Factor    Dry 

Rouge." 
Luzier  Rouge  " 

0.148  ounce.- 

$0.38. 

0.300  ounce 

$0.38. 

0.317  ounce... 

$1.00. 

Harriett     Hubbard 

0.315  ounce 

$0.55. 

Ayer      Cream 
Rouge." 
Elizabeth  Arden  Ve- 

0.357 ounce 

$1.00. 

netian  Lip  Paste." 

Springtime  in  Paris 
Lipstick. 19 

Bourjois  Sales  Corp. 
Lipstick." 

Coty's   Special   As- 
tringent." 

Harriett     Hubbard 

0.140  ounce 

$1.25. 

n  070  niinPA 

$0.55. 

4.000  ounces 

$1.00. 

11.993  ounces 

$1.75. 

Ayer  Special  As- 
tringent." 

4.000  ounces. 

$0.85. 

Freshner." 
Luzier  Skin  Refresh- 

1,910 nnncp.9 

$2.50 

ener." 
Elizabeth       Arden- 

2.323  ounces 

$2.00. 

Vcnetian   Derma- 

tex  Depilatory." 
Evening    in     Paris 

Perfume." 
Springtime  in  Paris 

Double  Vanity. 20 

0.550  ounce. 

$2.75. 

O.O.IS  nnnr.p. 

$1.75. 

0.566  ounce -.. 

$0.55. 

cle  Remover. 2" 
Barbara      O  o  u  1  d 

3.999  ounces...     - 

$0.45. 

Hand  Lotion.^' 
Food: 

Ovaltine  " 

14  ounces 

$0.75. 

Instant      Alberty's 

16  ounces 

$1.35. 

Food.28 

16  ounces.. -. 

$0.59. 

1  Journal  of  American  Medical  Association,  vol.  101,  No.  12,  Sept.  2,  1933,  p.  795. 

>  Ibid.,  vol.  101,  No.  3,  July  15,  1933,  p.  227. 

'  Retail  price  under  nonproprietary  name. 

<  Ibid.,  vol.  9S,  No.  8,  Feb.  20,  1932,  pp.  658-«60. 

» Ibid.,  vol.  98,  No.  4,  Jan.  23,  1932,  pp.  337,338. 

•  Ibid.,  vol.  85,  No.  1,  July  4,  192.'i,  p.  55. 

'  Ibid.,  vol.  92,  No.  10,  Mar.  9,  1929,  p.  828. 

•  Ibid.,  Apr.  8,  1933,  p.  1126. 

» Ibid.,  vol.  92,  No.  6,  Feb.  9,  1929,  pp.  492-495. 

">  Ibid.,  vol.  104,  No.  4,  Jan.  26,  1935,  pp.  335,  336. 

"  Ibid.,  vol.  109,  No.  14,  Oct.  2,  1937,  p.  1142. 

"  Ihid.,  vol.  102,  No.  4,  June  16,  1934,  pp.204!l  2042. 

"  Ibid.,  vol.  110,  No.  7,  Apr.  23,  1938,  p.  1385. 

"  Legislative  Document  of  the  State  of  Maine,  No.  683,  1935,  prepared  by  Dr.  O.  R.  Coomb,  director. 
Bureau  of  Health,  p.  26. 

"  Ibid.,  p.  27. 

"  Ibid.,  p.  28. 

"  Ibid.,  p.  29. 

"Ibid.,  p.  30. 

"Ibid.,  p.  31. 

"Ibid,  p.  32. 

"  Ibid.,  p.  33. 

"Ibid.,  p.  34. 

"  Ibid.,  p.  36. 

'*  Ibid.,  p.  35. 

"  Hearings  before  subcommittee  on  Interstate  and  Foreign  Commerce,  House  of  Representatives,  F.  R. 
6906,  H.  R.  8805,  H.  R.  8941,  and  S.  5,  July  and  August  1935,  p.  371. 

"Ibid.,  p.  381. 


84 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


In  particular,  the  price  of  items  sold  under  widely  advertised  brands 
often  shows  a  tendency  to  be  substantially  more  rigid  than  that  of 
similar  less  advertised  products.     For  example,  chart  IX  compares  the 


Chart  IX 


RETAIL    PRICES 

OF  MEN'S    DRESS    SHIRTS 

DOLLARS                                                                                                                                      DOLLARS 

PER  SHIRT                                                                                                                                   PER  SHIRT 

2.20 
200 

1  80 

2.00 
1.80 

,,—      '' 

\ 

\ 

^B^^^ 

V^ 

1  60 

\ 

^■^^ 

^^-^,, 

1 

1.60 

140 
1.20 
100 
80 
60 
40 
.20 

~ 

1.40 
1.20 
1  00 
80 
60 

.40 
.20 

1929        1930*     1931*     1932        1933        1934       1935*      1936       1937 

*         NO    DATA 

■c=«WIOELY    ADVERTISED     BRAND 

^■■■B  BRAND    NOT   Wl  DELY.  ADVERTISED 

US   BUREAU  OF  LABOR  STATISTICS 

trend  of  retail  prices  for  one  widely  adveitised  brand  of  men's  business 
shirts  with  the  average  of  a  number  of  less-known  brands  meeting  the 
same  general  specifications.  The  contrast  is  striking.  Retail  prices 
for  the  widely  advertised  product  showed  no  change  whatever  be- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


85 


tween  December  1929  and  December  1932,  whereas  the  average  for 
all  other  comparable  brands  declined  from  $1.91  to  $1.55. 

These  dijfferences  in  price  behavior  characterize  not  only  specific 
brands  but  also  the  general  class  of  commodity  to  which  the  brands 
apply.  For  example,  there  is  some  reason  for  believing  that  brand 
preference  plays  a  more  significant  role  in  the  market  for  corn  Hakes 
than  in  the  market  for  rolled  oats.  In  the  case  of  the  latter,  the 
product  is  somewhat  more  standardized  and  price  comparisons  between 
rival  brands  are  perhaps  simpler.  Chart  X  compares  the  trend  of 
wholesale  prices  and  ingredient  costs  for  these  two  commodities.  The 
contrast  is  marked.     The  price  of  corn  flakes  is  quite  rigid  and  appar- 


Chart  X 


BREAKFAST    CEREALS 

PRICES   AND   MARGINS 


i       CENTS 
PER   POUND 
22 


ROLLED   OATS 


CORN  FLAKES 


CENTS 
PER  POUND 


v^ 

x.^ 

,,^RETAIL 

>^^^ 

^^- 

WHOLESALE^^ 

y 

-^ 

X^./ 

y^ 

FARM  V 

,        .       ,        , 

1935         1937     \     I9'26  1930  1935         1937 

(I)  SOURCE     BUREAU   OF  AGRICULTURAL     ECONOMICS 


S    BUREAU    OF    LABOR    STATISTICS 


eiitly  independent  of  the  fluctuations  of  its  raw  material  costs.  It 
did  not  decline  at  all  between  1929  and  1933,  despite  the  fact  that  the 
cost  of  its  ingj'edicnts  declined  to  less  than  one-third  of  its  pre- 
depression  level.  During  th(i  same  peiiod,  the  wholesale  price  of  rolled 
oats  fell  about  39  percent,  paralleling  the  course  followed  by  the  price 
of  its  coustituents. 

A  more  general  comparison  may  be  made  on  the  basis  of  the  informal 
questioimaire,  to  which  reference  has  been  previously  made.  (See 
p.  78.)  The  60  products  for  which  data  were  obtained  were  ranked  and 
divided  into  four  groups  or  "quartiles",  each  group  including  approxi- 
mately the  same  number  of  items,  in  order  of  increasing  significance 
of  brand  prefeience.     The  average  wholesale  prices  foi-  each  quartile 


gg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

were  then  computed  for  the  period  between  January  1926  and  December 
1938.  These  items  for  which  brand  preference  was  a  relatively  sig- 
nificant market  factor  showed  far  greater  rigidity,  as  evidenced  by  their 
relatively  sm,aller  decline  during  the  depression,  as  v^ell  as  by  a  similar 
contrast  in  behavior  during  the  1937-38  recession.  This  comparison 
is  shown  in  chart  XI.  In  addition,  the  quartiles  were  also  compared 
on  the  basis  of  the  various  criteria  of  flexibility  described  in  appendix 
I.  This  comparison  is  shown  in  table  8.  Again  it  is  apparent  that 
brands  exert  a  distinct  influence  upon  price  flexibility,  regardless  of 
the  manner  in  which  it  is  computed.  Those  products  whose  markets 
are  relatively  unaffected  by  brand  preferences  showed  greater  fre- 
quency of  change,  greater  decline  during  the  depression,  and  greater 
recovery  subsequently. 

They  also  showed  some  tendency  to  respond  more  quickly  to  chang- 
ing business  trends,  particularly  during  the  recent  downturn.  Prices 
of  products  for  which  brand  preference  were  unimportant  declined 
after  Jirne  1937,  while  those  for  which  they  were  most  important  did 
not  start  falling  until  6  months  later. 

Table  8. — Relation  of  price  fexihility  to  importance  of  brand  preference — Median 
flexibility  according  to  specified  criteria,  for  selected  food  products,  grouped  into 
quartiles  on  the  basis  of  consumers'  judgment  as  to  brand  significance 

[Median  of  each  criterion  per  quartile] 


Criteria  of  flexibility 


Quartiles— in  order  of  in- 
creasing brand  signif- 
icance 


Number  of  changes  1926  to  April  1929 

Percent  decline,  June  1929  to  February  1933 

Percent  increase  from  depression  low— 1937  peak 

Percent  difference,  average  of  1929  peak  and  1937  peak,  less  depression  low  index. 

Aggregate  change  less  net  change,  1926  to  April  1929 _ 

Peak  month  of  1937  to  1938 


34 

55.0 
93.9 
57.9 
94.7 
6/37 


18 
45.8 
74.4 
45.5 
93.1 
6/37 


13 
34.3 
43.7 
39.5 
40.4 
9/37 


37.9 
44.6 

38.2 
15.7 
1,'38 


It  is  probable  that  the  effect  of  brands  and  trade-marks  upon  the  pat- 
tern of  competition  has  been  somewhat  affected  by  recent  legislative 
trends.  In  44  States,  under  the  so-called  fair-trade  laws,  the  manu- 
facturer of  a  trade-marked  article  can,  by  contract,  stipulate  the  min- 
imum price  at  which  such  an  article  may  be  resold  by  any  dealer  or 
distributor.  Under  the  provisions  of  these  laws,  once  such  a  contract 
has  been  signed  between  the  owner  of  the  trade-mark  and  any  dis- 
tributor within  a  State,  its  provisions  automatically  become  binding 
upon  all  other  distributors,  even  though  they  may  not  have  assented 
to  such  a  contract.  The  Federal  Miller-Ty dings  Act  exempts  con- 
tracts of  this  kind  between  trade-mark  owners  in  one  State  and  dis- 
tributors in  another  from  the  provisions  of  the  antitrust  laws. 
_  Wide  use  has  been  made  of  the  provisions  of  these  laws  in  connec- 
tion with  the  sale  of  dru^s,  toiletries,  cosmetics,  books,  and  Hquors; 
in  other  fields  such  as  radios  and  tobacco  products,  their  use  has  been 
more  sporadic.  Few  price-maintenance  contracts  have  been  issued 
for  grocery  products,  except  in  one  or  two  States,  notably  Ohio,  where 
minimum  prices  are  jxperimentally  established  for  a  very  few  staple 
products. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


87 


e> 


CO 

o 

o 

O 

o 

O 

o 

O 
< 

(/) 

o 

^,</) 

UJ 

-•h 

H 

H  CD 

o 

OC  < 

UJ 

<  X 

3 

_J 

O  O 

UJ 

z 

(n 

0=  >« 

Li. 
O 

o  qq2 

Ll.          " 

tr  <»> 

CO 

oiuS! 

UJ 

si" 

o 

a: 

en 

Q. 

UJ  o 

u.  o 

UJ 

-J 

mO 

< 

<^- 

(0 

_i 

UJ 

o 

-I 
o 

(0 

X 

o 

^ 

3 

O 

CC 

Q. 

UJ 

_l 

\ 

t 

< 

O 

o 

z 

/ 

^  J 

9 

o 

UJ 

X 

^" 

^ 

c> 

^ 

^^ 

y 

UJ  c  n 
-  ?  * 

a:  lo 

fe^ 

V^ 

> 

Ul 

-FOURTH 
Vfl  W>««f5  W 

1 

1?* 

0 

< 

O 

Q 

y^ 

l! 

^^ 

o  2 

^T 

? 

^ 

^ 

^ 

5 

O  ii  £  3 


:47149 — 41— No.  1- 


gg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  most  obvious  and  immediate  effect  of  this  legislation,  and  the 
one  primnrily  intended  by  its  sponsors,  has  been  the  reduction  or  elim- 
ination of  price  competition  between  retailers  in  connection  with  the 
sale  of  nationally  advertised  merchandise.  In  those  cases  in  which 
the  minimum  price  is  set  at  the  advertised  list  price,  there  is  no  room 
for  price  competition  as  regards  the  products  affected.  For  example, 
this  is  the  situation  which  prevails  with  regard  to  some  price-main- 
tained cosmetics.  Wliere  the  minimum  price  has  been  set  at  a  level 
below  list,  some  scope  for  price  competition  remains.  In  the  case  of 
branded  drugs,  for  example,  there  is  a  tendency  to  fix  the  minimum 
price  at  list  minus  20  percent,  minus  1  cent  (e.  g.,  if  the  list  price  is 
$1 ,  the  contract  minimum  is  79  cents;  if  list  is  75  cents,  contract  mini- 
mum is  59  cents;  if  list  is  50  cents,  contract  minimum  is  39  cents,  etc.). 
In  practice,  however,  there  may  be  some  tendency,  though  certainly 
not  a  universal  practice,  for  all  retailers  to  charge  the  contract 
minimum. 

Consequently,  the  focus  of  competition  between  retailers  in  the  fields 
most  affected  (i.  e.,  retail  druggists,  booksellers,  and  liquor  dealers) 
has  necessarily  shifted.  Those  stores  which  emphasize  price  appeal 
have  concentrated  their  efforts  upon  private  brands  which  are  not 
price  maintained.  One  leading  opponent  of  these  laws  has  made  its 
private  brands  available  to  any  retailers  who  wish  to  compete  on  a 
price  basis.  The  advertising  of  these  retailers  often  emphasizes  their 
private  brands  sold  at  reduced  prices.  Frequently,  the  advertising 
carries  detailed  technical  comparisons  designed  to  show  that  the 
product  bearing  the  private  brand  is  in  every  way  equivalent  to  the 
nationally  advertised,  price-maintained  article. 

On  the  other  band,  those  retailers  who  favor  the  principle  of  price 
maintenance  seized  upon  the  elimination  of  price  competition  as  an 
opportunity  to  feature  such  elements  as  service  or  convenience.^^ 

The  effect  of  price-maintenance  legislation  is  not  confined  to  the 
pattern  of  competition  between  distributors.  It  is  probable  that  it 
has  also  distinctly  influenced  manufacturers'  sales  strategy.  In  gen- 
eral, price-maintenance  contracts  provide  a  substantial  margin  for  the 
wholesaler  and  retailer.  Retail  drug  representatives  have  repeatedly 
insisted  upon  33!^  percent  of  selling  price — equivalent  to  50  percent  of 
cost — as  the  minimum  margin  acceptable.  The  manufacturer  who 
issues  the  contracts  has  therefore  decided  that  it  is  more  important 
for  him  to  retain  the  goodwill  of  his  distributors  than  to  appeal  to  the 
public  directly  by  selling  his  product  as  cheaply  as  possible. 

The  sales  manager  of  a  drug  manufacturer  summarizes  this  situa- 
tion succinctly  in  an  article  in  Printers'  Ink.^*  He  explains  to  a  critic 
why  manufacturers  issue  price-maintenance  contracts: 

If  he  has  followed  the  history  of  the  fair-trade  movement  he  should  know  that 
the  laws  were  forced  through  by  independent  retailers;  that  very  few  manufac- 

"  FuDflamentally,  this  controversy  is  not  so  much  one  between  individual  retailers  as  between  com- 
petine  channels  of  distribution.  The  mnjor  proponents  of  price  maintenance  are  members  of  the  tradi- 
tionnl  orthodox  channels  of  distribution;  that  is,  the  independent  wholesaler  and  the  relatively  small  inde- 
pendent retailer.  Aeainst  thcra  are  arrayed  some  of  the  mass  distributors,  particularly  large  department 
stores  and  mail-order  houses,  whr  usually  purchase  directly  fr-^m  the  manufacturer  rather  than  indirectly 
through  the  wholesaler.  However,  there  exists  certain  anomalies  in  this  line-up.  An  important  group  of 
mass  distributors,  the  brpe  national  drug  chains,  generally  support  price  maintenance.  The  reputation 
of  these  chains  was  originally  built  upon  price  appepl,  but  at  present  it  is  sufficiently  established  to  permit 
tijem  to  depend  upon  their  prestige  and  to  benefit  fr^^m  the  larger  [irofits  which  price  maintrnance  of.ers. 
On  fhe  other  hand,  a  number  of  smaller  units,  independents,  or  small  chains,  depend  largely  upon  price 
appeal  and  have  opposed  the  principle  of  price  maintenance. 

**  Printers'  Ink,  August  26,  19^7. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  89 

turcrs  hav'^e  taken  an  active  part  in  obta'ning  passage.  He  should  know,  al?o, 
that  in  the  drug  and  cosmetic  fields  many  manufacturers  are  being  compelled  to 
operate  under  these  laws  against  their  wishes  and  better  judgment.  Pressure  is 
being  brought  to  bear  through  the  retailers'  associations  and  their  fair-trade 
committees. 

Manufacturers  who  do  not  file  minimum  prices  arc  having  their  troubles  with 
independent  outlets  in  some  States.  Those  manufacturers,  such  as  ourselves, 
who  have  filed  prices  have  had  to  set  higher  minimums  than  they  desired  in  some 
instances.  The  committees  are  not  permitted,  supposedly,  by  law  to  dictate 
what  the  minimum  prices  shall  be  but  they  are  doing  just  that  by  refusing  to 
approve  contracts  containing  prices  which  do  not  give  the  retailer  what  they 
consider  to  be  a  fair-profit  margin.  In  most  cases  the  committees  are  insisting 
on  a  mark-up  of  at  least  20  percent  and  usually  33)i  percent. 

Ifc  is  not  surprising,  therefore,  that  many  drug  manufacturers,  in 
advertising  to  the  trade,  stress  the  high  margins  which  they  are  offer- 
ing the  retailer  on  sales  of  their  product.  The  following  advertise- 
ments, culled  at  random  from  various  drug  trade  periodicals,  illustrate 
this  trend.  Many  of  them  advertise  mark-ups  substantially  higher 
than  the  33}^  percent  minimum  demanded  by  the  trade: 

Even  at  minimum  prices — 10-cent  bottle  profit  when  you  sell  Squibb's  Milk  of 
Magnesia  12  ounces  at  minimum  29  cents." 

3|C  *  *  *  *  *  * 

Dr.  West's  Miracle  Tuft  Toothbrush,  retail  price  35  cents.  Weco's  policy  of 
price  and  profit  protection  by  every  legal  means  to  insure  full  20  cents  for  you 
ou  every  sale.^^ 

4c  *  *  f  *  *  * 

(Johnson  and  Johnson) — Fair  trade  minimums  protect  your  interest  and  give 
you  at  least  42  percent  average  profit." 

******* 
J.  &  J.  Red  Cross  Adhesive  Plaster:  Assortment  cost  $25.84 — your  profit  48.3 
percent — sell  at  $50.04.      *     *     *     At  fair  trade  minimums  you  meet  competition 
and  make  a  profit  of  48  percent  on  the  selling  price.'* 

******* 
Your  profits  up  from  that  big  45  percent  to  54  percent  on  Co-Ets  48's.^' 
******* 
Solarex — Dark  lens  glasses:  A  high  profit  on  all  Folarex  dark  lens  sun  glasses, 
assured   bv  strict  adherence   to   the    Miller-Tvdings  fair-trade  laws.      You   pay 
$10.80.     You  sell  for  $18.36.     Your  profit  "  $7.5fi. 

******* 
In  addition  to  offering  you  a  diversified  line  of  nationally  known,  popularly 
priced  products  of  high  quality,  we  prescribed  full  advertised  j>rices  to  insure 
you  a  satisfactory  profit.  You  can  buy  our  products  from  your  jobber,  or,  if  you 
prefer,  you  can  take  advantage  of  our  liberal  credit  terms,  which  range  from  3 
to  6  months  on  direct  purchases  in  quantities  as  small  as  $9.60,  yielding  an  aver- 
age profit  of  44  percent  *  *  *  Our  full  advertised  prices  are  our  minimum 
retail  prices.^' 

******* 
$6.60— Cost  Major  Donald  Duck  Deal,  90  assorted  packages,  1  large  $4  Major 
Donald  Duck,  1  Disney  Counter  Display,  sells  for  $]3.'"' 

*  :|c        •  *  *  *  * 

Fifty  percent  average  profit  on  all  McKesson  sales.*' 


"  Drug  Topics,  May  16,  1938,  p.  22. 
"  Ibid.,  Dcccmbf-r  12,  ]9ZS,  p.  5. 
"  Ibid  ,  July  18.  1939,  p.  7. 
'•Ibid.,  May  30.  1938.  p.  U. 
"Ibid..  April  3.  1939,  p.  6. 
<»Ibid  ,  March  fi.  1939.  pp.  8,  9. 
*'  Ibii.,  June  20,  lO'^S,  p  24. 
"  Ibid.,  March  r.,  1939,  p.  53. 
«  Ibid  ,  August  29.  1938,  p.  23. 


9Q  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Since  price  competition  between  rival  manufacturers  in  such  fields 
as  drugs  and  cosmetics  is  largely  ineffective  as  regards  branded  goods, 
price  maintenance  may  have  induced  some  reorientation  of  tactics 
by  concentrating  further  attention  upon  the  distributor  and  less  upon 
the  consumer. 

The  effects  of  price  maintenance  upon  price  behavior  have  been 
the  subject  of  much  controversy.  There  have  been  no  adequate 
impartial  surveys  conducted.  It  seems  probable,  however,  that  prices 
in  those  stores  which  used  to  feature  price  appeal  have  risen,  and  that 
perhaps  there  has  been  some  minor  decline  in  those  outlets  which 
competed  on  bases  other  than  price.  For  example,  the  July  1938  issue 
of  Dun's  Revio.w  compares  prices  for  50  fast  moving  drug  and  cosmetic 
items  in  the  State  of  New  York  before  and  after  the  issuance  of  price 
maintenance  contracts.  These  figures  show  that  for  those  drug  stores 
which  featured  price  appeal,  there  was  an  average  increase  of  29  per- 
cent. The  increase  of  one  item  was  as  high  as  67  percent.  In  contrast, 
neighborhood  drug  stores  which  did  not  compete  on  a  price  basis 
showed  an  increase  of  only  2  percent  in  New  York  City  and  decreases 
varying  from  4  percent  to  10  percent  in  smaller  cities.  However,  the 
entire  group  covered  included  only  40  stores.  Moreover,  the  data  for 
the  first  group  of  stores  were  obtained  through  the  cooperation  of  a 
trade  association  which  has  been  very  active  in  opposing  the  legisla- 
tion, while  those  for  the  second  group  were  obtained  through  the  aid 
of  an  association  which  had  been  its  vigorous  proponent.  Figures  of 
this  kind  are  particularly  hard  to  verify,  because  there  are  few,  if  any, 
drug  stores  which  maintain  records  of  the  prices  which  they  charged 
in  the  past.  Finally,  it  should  be  noted  that  the  general  trend  of 
wholesale  and  retail  prices  during  the  period  covered  was  downward. 
Consequently,  the  reliability  of  such  surveys  is  somewhat  questionable, 
though  with  very  broad  reservations  the  trend  displayed  may  have 
some  validity. 

It  seems  likely,  too,  that  price  maintenance  has  increased  price 
rigidity  in  the  wholesale  as  well  as  the  retail  markets  for  the  com- 
modities affected.  When  a  manufacturer  has  issued  contracts  in 
many  states  stipulating  minimum  resale  prices,  any  change  in  price 
involves  a  somewhat  complex  and  expensive  mechanical  process. 
It  has  already  been  shown  that  there  is  a  tendency  for  prices  of  branded 
goods  to  remain  relatively  rigid.  Price  maintenance,  by  making  it 
more  difiicult  to  initiate  price  changes,  has  perhaps  augmented  the 
tendency. 

It  is  apparent,  then,  that  brands,  particularly  for  consumer's 
goods,  must  be  considered  a  major  aspect  of  nonprice  competition. 
The  use  of  brands  and  trade-marks  materially  lessens  the  intensity 
of  price  competition  for  the  products  affected.  This  may  result  in  a 
level  of  prices  somewhat  higher  than  would  othery^ise  be  the  case. 
It  almost  certainly  impairs  price  flexibility.  Both  of  these  trends 
may  be  reinforced  by  price  maintenance  legislation,  though  adequate 
data  relating  to  its  efi'ects  are  unfortunately  lacking. 

OTHER    FORMS    OF   NONPRICE    COMPETITION — ESCAPE    DEVICES 

It  has  been  suggested  earlier  (pp.  55-56)  that  the  altering  focus  of 
competition  reflects  to  a  considerable  extent  the  attitude  of  business- 
men based  upon  considerations  of  expediency.     To  many  business 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  QJ 

firms  the  concentration  of  effort  upon  nonprice  factors  represents  a 
distinct  advantage,  particularly  as  regards  profit  margins  per  unit 
of  sales. 

These  considerations  of  expediency  do  not,  however,  apply  to  all 
kinds  of  business  firms  equally.  If  price  competition  is  absent, 
those  firms  which  are  best  equipped  to  compete  on  the  basis  of  quaUty, 
service,  or  prestige,  are  most  likely  to  retain  or  expand  their  shares 
of  the  market.  Conversely,  those  companies  whose  reputations  have 
yet  to  be  established  encoimter  distinct  difficulty  in  marketing  their 
wares  if  they  are  unable  to  offer  some  price  inducement. 

In  many  industries  this  situation  is  more  or  less  implicitly  recog- 
nized by  custom.  The  larger  **  and  better  known  companies  often 
permit  their  smaller  competitors  to  imdersell  them  by  a  slight  margin, 
thereby  permitting  them  to  compensate  in  price  for  their  disadvantage 
in  nonprice  competition.  It  may  be  considered  that  such  a  practice 
establishes  a  more  or  less  direct  price  equivalent  for  certain  intangible 
nonprice  elements. 

Naturally,  arrangements  of  this  sort  do  not  always  survive  periods 
of  stress.  During  an  acute  buyers'  market,  for  example,  price  often 
becomes  an  increasingly  important  competitive  weapon  and  is  used 
freely  even  by  those  whose  normal  tactics  and  inclinations  avoid  the 
use  of  price  competition.  During  such  periods,  the  small  firm's  edge 
often  becomes  reduced  or  obliterated.  Efforts  on  the  part  of  small 
firms  to  retain  their  edge  sometimes  culminate  in  severe  price  wars. 
Differences  of  this  kind  in  the  competitive  position  of  different  firms 
become  particularly  apparent  whenever  efforts  are  made  to  regulate 
market  practices.  Under  National  Recovery  Administration,  for 
example,  these  conflicts  of  interest  become  evident  in  many  industries. 

Price  regulation  constituted  an  important  aspect  of  many  of  the 
codes  of  fair  competition.  Regulations  which  tended  to  equalize 
prices  and  to  eliminate  price  competition  necessarily  placed  certain 
firms  at  a  marked  disadvantage.  Thus,  according  to  a  report  of  the 
Division  of  Industrial  Economics  summarizing  the  National  Recovery 
Administration  experience: 

In  whatever  way  uniform  prices  were  achieved,  their  intent  and  effect  were 
usually  to  impair  the  competitive  strength  of  those  concerns  that  had  formerly 
depended  upon  price  appeal.  In  the  retail  solid  fuel  industry,  for  example,  dis- 
tribution by  truck  had  expanded  markedly  during  the  depression.  Small  dis- 
tributors maintained  no  storage  yards,  but  bought  truckloads  from  the  mine  or 
the  freight  terminal  and  delivered  directly  to  the  consumer.  Since  their  service 
was  often  irregular  and  their  prestige  not  well  established,  they  could  obtain 
business  only  by  price  concessions.  The  effect  of  the  industry's  minimum 
prices  was  to  deprive  them  of  their  selling  argument  and  also  to  weaken  the  very 
small  coal  yards. 

******* 

In  the  Cleaning  and  Dyeing  Trade  the  cash-and-carry  cleaners  contended  that 
they  could  not  keep  their  business  unless  they  were  permitted  to  sell  below  the 
prices  of  those  cleaners  who  receive  and  deliver  the  garment  at  the  customer's 
residence.  Their  refusal  to  abide  by  the  uniform  minimum  prices  established 
under  the  code  was  an  important  factor  in  the  breakdown  of  the  price  structure. 
In  the  Wholesale  Confectionery  Trade  a  cash-and-carry  wholesaler  complained  to. 
a  member  of  his  local  code  authority  that  he  must  either  allow  a  larger  discount 
than  his  competitor  who  delivered  merchandise  and  extended  credit  or  else  go 
out  of  business.     Aa  he  later  described  the  conversation:  "The  answer  was  this,. 

"  In  manufacturing  industries  the  advantage  of  prestive  is  usually,  though  not  always,  on  the  side  of  the 
largo,  well-established  firms.  In  the  retail  and  wholesale  trades,  however,  it  is  often  the  srhaller  independent 
concern  which  prefers  to  compete  on  grounds  other  than  price. 


g2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

'Mr.  Lieberman,  you  have  been  a  cash-and-carry  man.  From  today  on  you 
will  become  a  service  man.'  I  said,  'You  are  a  code  authority  lawyer  today; 
what  would  happen  if  someone  wanted  you  to  become  a  criminal  lawyer?  Would 
you  like  that'  "  '^ 

In  other  industries,  prestige,  rather  than  service,  was  a  factor. 
Thus  in  the  business  furniture  industry  there  was  a  serious  conflict 
between  the  large  manufacturers  who  depended  upon  their  established 
reputation  and  smaller  ones  who  could  only  operate  on  the  basis  of 
price  appeal.  Any  program  designed  to  eliminate  price  competition 
seemed  congenial  to  the  interests  of  the  larger  producers.  The  con- 
flict in  point  of  view  between  those  who  favored  price  competition  and 
those  who  wished  to  eliminate  it  entirely  in  favor  of  nonprice  com- 
petition is  clearly  revealed  in  the  following  extract  from  a  National 
Recovery  Administration  hearing.  A  speaker  representing  a  very 
large  producer  stated: 

One  of  the  serious  difficulties  in  our  business  has  been  that  the  large  manu- 
facturers by  means  of  their  designers,  and  advertising  and  other  promotional 
efforts  have  created  a  demand  for  these  products — you  will  recall  that  there  is, 
after  all,  no  particular  demand  for  these  products  unless  it  is  created — whereas  the 
small  dealers  undersell,  and  undercut  the  eflForts  of  these  large  manufacturers,  and 
the  results  in  the  past  have  been  most  disastrous. 

*  :i!  *  *  *  *  * 

The  manufacturers  who  have  developed  these  goods  and  the  dealers  who  have 
sold  it  (sic)  and  created  the  demand  must  not  have  their  business  taken  away  from 
them— or  all  the  profits  taken  away,  which  amounts  to  the  same  thing,  by  small 
manufacturers  or  small  dealers  from  over  the  other  side  of  the  track,  who  are 
willing  to  sell  at  any  price  and  thus  spoil  what  was  once  a  profitable  business. 

Our  code  provides  that  there  shall  be  no  discrimination  against  the  little  fellow 
but  nowhere,  in  any  code,  have  I  seen  any  reference  to  the  small  operator  being 
entitled  to  protection  or  an  "edge"  at  the  expense  of  the  larger  group.  The  small 
operator  is  entitled  to  all  the  business  he  can  get  on  the  right  terms  and  on  equal 
terms  with  the  rest  of  the  industry. 

The  representative  of  the  Consumers'  Advisory  Board  replied: 

Mr.  BoFFEY.  You  made  the  statement  that  the  small  operator  should  not  be 
allowed  to  take  advantage  of  the  big  operator. 

Mr.  Keeling.  I  feel  that  very  keenly. 

Mr.  BoFFEY.  As  between  the  small  operator  with  limited  sales  promotion, 
and  the  large  manufacturer  who  is  able  to  use  advertising  and  create  consumer 
demand,  who  is  going  to  get  the  order  from  the  consumer  on  an  equal  basis? 

Mr.  Keeling.  I  would  like  to  answer  that  in  a  rather  roundabout  way.  Bear 
in  mind  this,  that  all  the  large  manufacturers  were  small  at  one  time,  and  collec- 
tively, and  in  some  cases  individually,  they  have  spent  millions  of  dollars  in  devel- 
oping this  business,  and  any  small  manufacturer  has  the  right  to  come  in  tomorrow 
and  open  up  a  little  shop  in  a  back  alley  some  place,  but  there  is  no  obligation  on 
my  part  to  hold  an  umbrella  over  him  and  protect  him  until  he  is  a  responsible 
competitor.  He  is  entitled  to  all  the  business  he  can  get  on  even  terms.  When 
my  firm  started  we  asked  no  odds  of  anyone,  and  there  are  many  other  manu- 
facturers who  did  the  same  thing.  They  started  in  business  and  went  out  on  even 
competition  and  built  their  business  up,  and  there  are  many  examples  of  manu- 
facturers who  have  started  within  the  last  10  years  and  have  built  up  a  substantial 
business  and  asked  no  quarter  of  anyone.  There  are  many  manufacturrers  doing 
business  in  a  loft,  or  in  a  back  alley.  They  claim  a  preference  and  a  protection 
they  are  not  entitled  to.  The  small  dealer  is  not  entitled  to  any  protection.  He 
is  entitled  to  all  the  business  he  can  get  on  the  right  terms. 

Mr.  Rauch.  You  also  referred  to  there  being  no  reason  why  the  large  producer 
should  hold  an  umbrella  over  the  small  producer.  You  don't  mean  to  infer  by 
that  if  the  small  producer  does  not  incur  a  large  advertising  expense,  for  example, 
he  should  be  compelled  to  sell  at  a  price  which  would  include  that  expense? 

«•  Miniipum  Price  Control— Stafl  Studies— Division  of  Industrial  Economics,  ch.  II,  pp.  53,  57,  58. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  93 

Mr.  Keeling.  I  didn't  mean  that,  but  I  mean  this:  If  I  have  a  file  of  a  certain 
grade  as  the  man  across  the  street  who  is  just  going  into  the  business  makes, 
he  has  no  right  to  undermine  me  by  underselling  me..  I  like  him  personally  and 
all  that  sort  of  stuff,  but  I  am  not  going  to  pat  him  on  the  shoulder  and  give  him  a 
couple  of  dollars  every  time  he  sells  a  file.  When  my  company  started  we  asked 
no  quarter;  we  went  out  and  got  the  business,  so  I  see  no  reason  for  any  edge  or 
protection  from  anyone  in  any  line  of  activity.  Let  them  go  out  and  meet  com- 
petitive conditions  as  they  find  them.     That  is  the  way  we  feel  about  it. 

Mr.  Rauch.  You  maintain,  do  you  not,  that  the  small  individual  has  the  right 
to  file  any  price  he  wants,  and  you  have  the  right  to  meet  it? 

Mr.  Keeling.  That  is  right.  Any  manufacturer  has  the  right  to  file  any  price 
he  chooses  at  any  time,  but  when  once  filed,  he  must  sell  at  that  price.  He  can 
change  it  at  any  time,  but  he  must  file  his  change,  and  anybody  has  got  the  right 
to  go  out  and  meet  him.''^ 

A  somewhat  similar  situation  occurred  in  the  tire-manufacturing 
industry,  where  again  it  seems  that  smaller  manufacturers  could 
compete  with  the  larger  only  on  the  basis  of  price.  The  consequences 
of  the  code  provision  designed  to  limit  the  freedom  of  price  competition 
were  expressed  by  a  small  producer  in  the  following  words: 

We  don't  want  to  sell  below  cost.  We  don't  propose  to  sell  below  cost,  but 
you  notice  what  they  add  to  it.  Nobody  must  sell  below  cost  unless  to  meet 
competition. 

Well,  up  here  is  a  big  manufacturer.  Everybody  knows  he  has  to  sell  above  us 
if  he  can  make  money.  He  can  do  it  and  has  consumer  acceptance  that  carries 
him  on.  He  would  starve  if  he  sold  at  our  price.  There  is  no  question  about  it. 
He  does  not  have  to.  He  keeps  on  advertising.  Here  is  our  cost.  He  does  not 
have  to  sell  at  his  cost  when  he  meets  our  competition,  so  he  can  come  down  and 
meet  us  and  we  have  not  any  right  under  the  formula  to  fall  below;  in  other  words, 
as  I  have  heretofore  said,  w-e  are  chained  to  a  post,  and  he  comes  and  gets  us  and 
sells  against  us  as  long  as  he  wants  to  because  of  that  provision.  Don't  you  see 
where  it  all  leads?  ^' 

Illustrations  of  this  kind  could  be  multiplied  indefinitely.  Enough 
has  been  said,  however,  to  show  that  a  sliift  from  price  competition 
to  nonprice  competition  may  not  benefit  all  the  firms  in  an  industry 
equally,  even  if  the  longer  term  aspects  of  the  issue  be  neglected. 
In  general,  established  concerns  are  often  content  to  retain  their 
positions  in  the  industry,  and  to  avoid  price  competition,  while  growing 
companies  must  use  aggressive  tactics  to  expand  their  shares  of  the 
market. 

One  procedure  for  equalizing  the  situation  has  already  been  sug- 
gested; that  is,  a  state  of  affairs  in  which  firms  with  superior  prestige 
permit  those  whose  prestige  is  inferior  to  charge  a  somewhat  lower 
price.  Where  this  alternative  is  unavailable,  either  because  members 
of  the  industry  do  not  accept  the  custom  or  because  of  some  form  of 
price  regulation,  other  devices  have  been  attempted.  Under  National 
Recovery  Administration,  for  example,  an  amazing  degree  of  ingenuity 
was  displayed  in  devising  new  forms  of  competition  to  take  the  place 
of  those  prohibited  by  the  codes.  Quoting  again  from  the  report  of 
the  Division  of  Industrial  Economics: 

Wherever  minimum-price  systems  cause  peculiar  difficulties  for  one  part  of  an 
industry,  there  was  a,  direct  incentive  to  evade  or  destroy  the  minimum  prices. 
Minimum-price  provisions  were  consequently  difficult  to  enforce. 

Opportunities  for  evasion  were  manifold.  Since  the  code  provisions  had  been 
hastily  written,  legal  ways  of  selling  below  the  minimum  prices  could  often  be 
discovered.  Even  the  most  carefully  drawn  code  provision  was  seldom  an  adequate 
check  upon  a  determined  price  cutter.     Price  concessions  could  be  made  by 

«  Ibid.,  pp.  54,  55,  56. 
"Ibid.,  p.  56. 


94  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

greater  liberality  in  the  quality  or  quantity  of  the  product  or  in  any  of  the  accessory 
services  or  terms  of  sale;  and  to  regulate  every  detail  of  each  transaction  was 
impossible. 

In  the  sale  of  tires  prices  could  be  cut  by  extending  the  duration  of  guaranties 
of  performance.  Price  concessions  in  the  retail  sale  of  automobiles  consisted 
largely  of  higher  trade-in  allowances  upon  used  cars.  In  the  lumber  and  bitu- 
minous coal  industries,  price  cutters  delivered  better  grades  than  had  been  ordered 
and  paid  for.  Inthe  bituminous  coal  industry  some  producers  offered  guarantees 
which  their  customers  knew  were  excessive  and  contracted  to  forfeit  a  part  of  the 
price  if  the  coal  was  below  the  guaranteed  standard.  In  many  industries  premiums 
or  free  deals  were  used  to  reduce  the  net  price.  Some  producers  attracted  trade 
by  offering  lavish  entertainment  to  buyers.  Others  offered  unusually  liberal  cash 
discounts  and  credit  terms.  Long-term  contracts  whose  date  was  alleged  to  be 
prior  to  the  minimum  price  system  served  as  excuses  for  sales  at  low  prices  to 
favored  customers. 

******* 

Successive  efforts  to  plug  loopholes  in  minimum-price  provisions  made  the 
provisions  increasingly  complicated.  Detailed  regulation  of  terms  of  sale  decreased 
the  flexibility  of  business  transactions,  caused  inconvenience  to  many  concerns 
which  were  not  using  the  prohibited  practices  to  evade  the  code,  and  multiplied 
the  points  at  which  governmental  supervisions  and  enforcement  were  required. 
Petty  regulations  became  so  complicated  that  in  some  instances  they  were  a 
nuisQ,nce  both  to  the  industry  and  to  the  administration.  An  example  of  the 
detailed  character  thus  given  to  Federal  law  is  the  stipulation  in  the  Retail  Tobacco 
Code  that  "the  retailer  may  give  not  more  than  1  pad  of  matches  for  each  unit  sold 
or  5  pads  per  box  of  25  cigars,  or  10  pads  per  box  of  50  cigars  sold."  *^ 

Perhaps  the  best  commentary  on  the  variety  of  forms  which  compe- 
tition can  assume  and  the  variety  of  ways  in  which  price  quotations 
can  be  indirectly  modified  is  the  following  list  of  the  types  of  regulation 
which  were  attempted  under  National  Recovery  Administration  in  the 
eflFort  to  regulate  all  forms  of  competitive  tactics.  This  summary  of 
code  provisions  is  in  a  sense  an  index  to  all  the  varieties  of  nonprice 
competition  with  which  business  men  in  various  industries  were 
reasonably  familiar,  though  even  these  did  not  include  all  the 
possibilities. 

Types  of  Concessions  to  Influence  Sales  as  Dealt  with  by  Codes 

1.  Concessions  primarily  related  to  time  of  buyer's  payment: 

Discounts. 

"Terms"  and  "conditions"  of  sale  or  payment. 

Credit  practices. 

Credit  terms. 

Cash  discounts. 

Periods  of  free  credit. 

Interest  rate  beyond  free-credit  period. 

Datings. 

Seasonal  datings. 

Installment  sales. 

Deferred  payment. 

Anticipation  of  bills. 

Sales  to  delinquent  accounts. 

Sales  not  contingent  upon  buyer's  credit  standing. 

Payment  due  when  money  received  from  other  sources. 

Retained  percentages. 

2.  Concessions  primarily  related  to  risks  of  buyer: 

Guarantees. 

Price  guarantees. 

Contracts  for  deferred  delivery  not  subject  to  price  change. 

Price  offer  not  subject  to  change. 

Advance  notification  of  price  change. 

Delaying  acceptance  of  order. 

"Ibid.,pp.  70,  72. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWEU  95 

Options. 

Agreements  indefinite  as  to  time  or  quantity. 

Offers  w  ithout  time  limit. 

Offers  not  expiring  within  specified  period  of  time. 

Offers  without  withdrawal  provisions. 

Guaranties  against  defective  goods. 

Product  guarantees. 

Product  guarantees  against  other  than  defective  merchandise. 

Uniform  product  guarantees  specified  in  code. 

Guarantees    in    excess    of    manufacturers'    warranty     (distributing    and 

fabricating  codes). 
Maintenance  guarantees. 
Adjusting  incorrect  shipments. 
Accepting  return  of  merchandise. 

Accepting  return  of  obsolete,  discontinued  or  "unsalable"  merchandise. 
Exchanging  merchandise. 

Accepting  return  of  other  than  defective  merchandise. 
Repurchase  agreements. 
"Money-back    agreements. 
Sales  subject  to  trial. 
Sales  on  approval. 
Shipments  without  order. 
Sales  on  consignment  or  memorandum. 
Storing  goods  with  customer. 
Display  for  direct  sale  in  customer's  store. 
Renting  or  leasing  industry  products. 
Resale  guarantees. 

Agreeing  that  payment  be  governed  by  sales  of  secondary  product. 
Accepting  orders  for  specific  jobs  before  customer  secures  award. 
Guaranteeing  accounts  due  customers. 
"Compensation  of  customer  for  business  losses." 
Unilateral  agreements  (buyer  not  bound). 
Contracts  containing  penalty  clauses. 
Contracts  containing  liquidated  damages  clauses. 
Contracts   not   subject   to   adjustment   necessitated   by   noncontrollable 

factors. 
Assuming  liability  for  nonperformance  caused  by  noncontrollable  factors. 
Assuming  liability  for  damage  to  buyer's  drawings  or  equipment  caused 

by  noncontrollable  factors. 
Assuming  liability  foi*  errors  in  plans  or  specifications  furnished  or  approved 

by  buyer. 
Assuming  liability  for  consequential  damages. 
Assuming  liability  for  patent  infringement. 
Failure  to  give  advance  notice  of  discontinued  lines. 
3.  Concessions  primarily  related  to  supplying  additional  goods: 
Any  gratuities. 
Free  deals 
Premiums. 

Sales  of  other  or  additional  goods  at  reduced  prices. 
Combination  sales. 
Combination  offers. 
Coupons. 
Samples. 
Scrip  books. 
Prices. 

Sales  promotion  awards. 
Containers. 
Special  containers. 
Labels. 

Special  labels. 
Special  equipment. 
Accessories. 

Certain  advertising  material. 
Display  materials. 
Printed  matter  (other  than  advertising  material). 


96  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

4.  Concessions  rendered  buyer  through  use  of  seller's  employees  or  property. 

Any  unusual  service. 

Providing  sales  help. 

Demonstrating. 

Estimating. 

Furnishing  drawings. 

Furnishing  plans  and  specifications. 

Furnishing  surveys  and  formulas. 

Tnstaljation  and  erection. 

Inspections. 

Furnishing  unusual  processing  services  soecified  in  codes. 

Stampings  or  markings. 

Repair  and  maintenance. 

Reconditioning. 

Engineering  services. 

Handling. 

Crating  or  packing. 

Repacking. 

Delivery  service  by  seller's  trucks. 

Warehousing  and  storage. 

Lending  of  equipment. 

Permitting  retention  of  trade-in  equipment. 

5.  Concessions  rendered  buyer  through  financial  assistance  or  favors: 

Favors. 

Entertainment. 

Patronizing  publications  in  which  buyfer  is  interested. 

Participating  in  group  showing. 

Gifts. 

Gifts  to  organizations  (in  which  buyer  is  interested). 

Paying  buyer's  personal  expenses. 

Paying  permit  or  inspection  fees  of  buyer. 

Paying  customer's  insurance. 

Paying  customer's  advertising  expenses  for  products  other  than  member's 

Assuming  reversed  telephone  or  telegraph  charges. 

Assisting  customer  to  obtain  used  products  for   trade-ins. 

Assisting  customer  to  find  purchaser  for  used  products. 

Subsidizing  or  financing  buyer. 

Employing  customers,  employees,  relatives,  associates. 

Purchase  of  buyer's  capital  stock. 

Financing  payments  due  customer. 

6.  Concessions  related  to  manner  and/or  time  of  shipment: 

Split  shipments. 

Shipments  smaller  than  specified  minimum. 

Tolerance  in  time  of  shipment 

Deferred  delivery. 

7.  Concessions  through  payment  or  diversion  of  commissions  or  fees  to  customer: 

Payment  of  commissions  or  fees  by  members  to  buyers. 

Payment  of  commissions  or  fees  by  members  to  other  than  bona  fide  or 
controlled  sales  representatives. 

Payment  of  commissions  or  fees  by  members  to  purchasing  agents  com- 
pensated by  buyers. 

Payment  of  commissions  or  fees  by  agents  of  members  to  buyers. 

Splitting  of  commissions  or  fees  by  agents  of  members  with  agents  of 
buyers  without  buyer's  knowledge. 

Splitting  of  commissions  or  fees  by  members  or  their  agents  with  buyers 
or  their  agents. 

Payment  of  brokerage  to  other  than  bona  fide  brokers. 

8.  Concessions  through  allowances  or  payments  for  value  rendered  by  buyer: 

Allowances. 
Trade-in  allowances. 
Advertising  allowances. 
Catalogue  allowances. 
Distribution  service  allowances. 
Container  allowances. 
Installation  allowances. 
Allowance  for  further  processing. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC.  POWER  97 

Maintenance  or  repair  allowance. 

Rental  allowances  for  space  hired. 

Allowance  on  supplies  furnished  by  purchaser  for  production  of  product 

ordered. 
Cartage  allowances  when  buyer  receives  goods  at  factory. 
Allowance  for  special  service. 
Label  allowances. 
Purchasing  from  buyer. 
Renting  from  buyer. 

9.  Concessions  through  acceptance  of  competitor's  materials  from  buyers: 

Exchange  of  own  for  competitor's  products. 
Purchase  of  competitor's  products  from  customer. 

10.  Concessions  through  sale  of  substandard  or  obsolete  goods: 

Sale  of  seconds. 

Sale  of  used  goods. 

Sale  of  damaged  goods. 

Sale  of  rebuilt  or  overhauled  goods. 

Sale  of  demonstrators. 

Sale  of  obsolete  goods. 

Sale  of  discontinued  lines. 

Willful  manufacture  of  substandard  products. 

Sale  of  returns. 

Sale  of  scrap. 

Sale  of  chaflF. 

Sale  of  culled  goods. 

Sale  of  surplus  stock. 

11.  Concessions  granted  during  performance  contrary  to  provisions  of  agreement: 

Rebates. 

Departure  from  credit  t-erms  of  contract. 

Settlement  of  old  accounts  at  less  than  full  value. 

Permitting  improper  deductions  when  buyer  remits. 

Permitting  buyer's  cancelation  or  repudiation. 

Substitution  of  higher  quality  or  greater  quantity  of  goods. 

Substitution  of  new  contract  at  lower  price. 

Receipting  bills  before  payment. 

Extending  or  exceeding  contract. 

Collateral  agreement  not  to  enforce  part  of  contract. 

Departure  from  delivery  date  of  contract. 

Retroactive  settlement  or  adjustments. 

12.  Acceptance  of  forms  of  payment  in  which  concessions  may  be  concealed: 

Accepting  securities. 

Accepting  buyer's  capital  stock. 

Accepting  goods  from  buyer. 

Accepting  real  or  personal  property. 

Accepting  negotiable  instruments. 

Accepting  other  than  lawful  money. 

Accepting  credit  transferred  from  one  buyer  to  another. 

Selling  for  customer  account  and  accepting  proceeds  for  credit. 

Accepting  form  of  payment  other  than  specified  in  code. 

Accepting  rental  payments  as  part  payment  on  purchases. 

Accepting  deposit  made  to  another  manufacturer. 

Assignments  (of  receivables,  etc.). 

13.  Types  of  agreements,  offers,  invoicing,  etc.,  by  means  of  which  concessions 

may  be  concealed: 
Oral  agreements. 
Oral  offers. 
Oral  appraisals. 
Oral  orders. 
False  billing. 
False  orders. 
False  receipts. 
False  agreements. 
False  offers. 
Delayed  billing. 
Misdated  invoices. 
Misdated  contracts. 


gg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Misdated  orders. 
Misdated  offers. 
Misdated  receipts. 
Invoices  omitting  terms  of  sale. 
Invoices  omitting  date  of  shipment. 
Invoices  omitting  specifications. 
Invoices  omitting  other  specified  detail. 
Agreements  omitting  terms  of  sale. 
Agreements  omitting  date  of  shipment. 
Agreements  omitting  specifications. 
Agreements  omitting  other  specified  detail. 
Offers  omitting  terms  of  sale. 
Offers  omitting  <late  of  shipment. 
Offers  omitting  specifications. 
Offers  omitting  other  specified  detail. 
Orders  omitting  terms  of  sale. 
Orders  omitting  date  of  shipment. 
Orders  omitting  specifications. 
Orders  omitting  other  specified  detail. 
Split  billing. 
Lump  sum  offers. 
UniteWeed  billing. 

Orders  not  subject  to  member's  acceptance. 
Auction  sales. 
14.  Types  of  agreements,  offers,  invoicing,  etc.,  primarily  designed  to  prevent  the 
concealing  of  concessions: 
Uniform  contract  form. 
Uniform  order  form. 
Uniform  bid  or  quotation  form. 
Standard  invoice  form. 
Standard  leasing  form. 
Form  of  contract. 

It  is  apparent  then  that  trade-practice  regulation,  such  as  that 
practiced  undei*  the  National  Recovery  Administration,  often  serves  to 
divert  the  focus  of  competition.  However,  it  may  not  prevent  or 
stifle  it;  emphasis  shifts  from  those  aspects  of  the  transaction  which 
are  regulated  to  others  which  are  free  of  control. 

The  National  Recovery  Administration  experience  was  used  to 
illustrate  this  point  because  it  covered  so  wide  a  sector  of  industry 
and  because  of  the  wealth  of  data  available  as  to  its  effects.  How- 
ever, the  phenomena  observed  are  by  no  means  unique  to  that  period. 
Similar  shifts  in  competitive  emphasis  are  constantly  occurring,  not 
only  because  of  the  impact  of  Government  regulation  but  also  as  a 
result  ol  all  the  constantly  changing  pressure  to  which  the  business- 
man is  subjected  during  the  ordinary  conduct  of  his  affairs. 

Thus,  it  is  often  hiexpedient  for  the  individual  firm  to  change  its 
nominal  price  quotations  to  secure  large  individual  orders.  To  do 
so  may  arouse  the  resentment  both  of  competing  sellers  and  of  buyers 
not  equally  favored ;  since  the  Robinson-Patman  Act  was  passed  it 
may  even  be  illegal  to  do  so.  Consequently,  many  devices  similar 
to  those  considered  in  connection  with  National  Recovery  Adminis- 
tration are  utilized  to  grant  indirect  concessions  in  unregulated  mar- 
kets, as  well  as  in  those  subject  to  some  form  of  Government  control. 

Frequently  these  concessions  amount  so  directly  to  modifications 
of  the  nominal  or  quoted  price  that  they  arc  not,  properly  speaking, 
aspects  of  nonprice  competition.  However,  since  they  are  not  usually 
reflected  in  published  price  statistics,  they  must  be  accorded  diie 
weight  in  any  interpretation  of  the  movements  of  price  indexes. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


99 


An  excellent  illustration  is  afforded  by  the  market  for  sulfuric 
acid.  The  published  price  quotation  for  thi^s  commodity  is  remark- 
ably rigid.  It  showed  no  change  at  all  between  November  1927  and 
May  1937.  In  all  probability,  moreover,  this  quotation  accurately 
reflects  what  the  small  buyer  was  required  to  pay  during  this  period. 

However,  there  is  evidence  that  a  very  material  share  of  the  total 
sulfuric  acid  production  is  sold  on  the  basis  of  contracts  covering  a 
period  of  a  year  or  longer.  The  prices  stipulated  in  these  contracts 
seem  to  be  subject  to  material  modification  by  bargaiiimg.  They 
are  probably  substantially  lower  than  the  published  quotation  at  all 
times,  and  also  seem  to  show  appreciably  greater  flexibility. 

Thus,  the  following  table  contrasts  the  nominal  quotations  as  re- 
ported by  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  with  the  actual  prices  paid 
by  a  large  buyer: 


Table  9.- 


-Comparison  of  quoted  prices  for  sulfuric  acid  with  prices  actually  paid 
by  a  large  buyer 


Year 

Average  quoted 

price  per  ton 

(converted  to 

100-percent 

basis)  ' 

Price  paid  by 
large  buyer  per 
ton  (100-per- 
cent basis)  2 

Year 

Average  quoted 

price  per  ton 

(converted  to 

100-pcrccnt 

basis)  ' 

Price  paid  by 
large  buyer  per 
ton  (100-per- 
cent basis)  2 

1926 

$15.  67 
16.20 
16.63 

$15.35 
15.94 
15.73 
12.85 
12.18 
12.37 

1932     . 

$16.  63 
16.63 
16.  03 
16.63 
16.63 
17.21 

$12  38 

1927.. 

1928 

1933 

1934 . 

12.25 
14.96 

1029 _.'                   16.63 

1930 16.63 

1935 

1936 

14.68 

1931 

16.63 

1937 

13.52 

'  The  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  quotation  was  for  66°  B  acid.  It  was  converted  to  a  100-percent  basis 
by  dividing  by  0.932,  which  is  the  acid  content  of  06°  acid.  This  basis  of  conversion  is  approximate,  but  it 
is  adequate  for  the  purpose  of  comparison. 

'  All  these  prices,  with  the  exception  of  the  year  1934,  were  on  the  basis  of  contracts  for  the  period  of  1 
year  or  longer.    The  1934  price  represented  noncontract  purchases. 

Sometimes  wide  concessions  below  the  quoted  price  level  are  made 
available  to  buyers  generally,  rather  than  to  selected  customersr  Re- 
ported and  published  prices  remain  stable,  while  the  level  at  which 
business  is  being  transacted  fluctuates  sharply.  The  National  Re- 
sources Committee  cites  the  following  examples  of  this  technique  in 
a  report  just  published.*^ 

(1)  The  fertilizer  industry. — Some  clue  to  the  extent  to  which  rebates  and  con- 
cessions affect  nominal  fertilizer  prices  may  be  obtained  from  a  report  of  the 
Federal  Trade  Commission. s"  According  to  this  report,  there  was  widespread 
selling  of  fertilizer  at  prices  far  below  list  during  the  years  1921  and  1922.  The 
Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  index  showed  no  change  in  price  between  January 
and  December  1921.  It  showed  a  substantial  cut  between  December  1921  and 
January  1922,  and  perfectlj'  stable  price  quotations  through  1922.  According  to 
the  Trade  Commission,  however,  "in  192i  and  1922  price  lists  were  published  as 
usual,  but  were  so  high  that  the  companies  were  unable  to  maintain  such  prices 
for  any  length  of  time."  The  Commission  reproduced  many  letters  taken  from 
the  files  of  fertilizer  manufacturers  which  reveal  the  extent  to  which  rebating  was 
practiced.  During  this  period,  for  example,  Swift  &  Co.  were  selling  to  dealers 
at  discounts  of  33.3  percent  plus  5  percent  off  schedule,  and,  in  addition,  granting 
a  direct  rebate  of  $2  per  ton.  The  American  Chemical  Co.  instructed  its  North 
Carolina  sales  managers  to  go  as  far  as  33.3  percent  below  list  wherever  necessary 

"  The  Structure  of  the  American  Economy,  National  Resources  Committee,  pt.  I,  June  19?Q.  p.  178. 

*>  Fertilizer  Industry.  Letter  from  the  Actmg  Chairman  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  transmitting 
in  response -to  «  Senate  resolution  ot  June  17,  1922,  a  report  on  certain  phases  of  the  fertiliier  industry.  S. 
Doc.  347,  67th  Cong.,  4tb  soss. 


^QQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

to  meet  competition.  On  April  10,  1922,  *  *  *  a,  district  manager  of  the 
American  Agricultural  Chemical  Co.  wrote  to  its  vice  president:  "I  think  every 
concern  operating  out  of  Atlanta,  with  no  exception,  is  making  almost  any  price 
it  sees  fit  in  order  to  get  some  business.  *  *  *  All  managers  and  division 
managers  practically  admit  that  there  is  no  regular  price." 

Although  similar  documentary  evidence  is  not  available  for  periods  subsequent 
to  1921  and  1922,  persons  close  to  the  trade  state  that  similar  practices  have  re- 
curred under  similar  conditions. 

(2)  Salt  industry.— A  parallel  situation  occurred  in  the  salt  industry  during  the 
latter  part  of  1935.  *  *  *  Price  quotations  show  no  decline  from  March  to 
September  1935.  Yet,  according  to  a  National  Recovery  Administration  study, 
a  price  war  started  early  in  1935  and  discounts  of  as  much  as  30  percent  were 
being  granted  by  August  1935.     According  +o  this  report — 

"Particularly  during  time  of  depression,  in  efforts  to  bolster  declining  sales 
volume,  many  members  of  the  industry  offered  secret  prices,  discounts,  rebates, 
and  other  concessions     *     *     *_ 

"In  the  latter  months  of  the- code  period,  the  practice  of  granting  secret  rebates 
atid  other  secret  concessions  from  filed  prices  began  to  develop  in  the  industry. 
Filed  prices  were  maintained  at  uniform  levels  within  the  various  marketing  areas, 
but  actual  price  uniformity  was  disappearing.  The  difficulty  of  discovering  and 
proving  secret  price  concessions,  plus  rather  apathetic  support  from  the  National 
Recovery  Administration  along  compliance  lines,  contributed  to  the  growth,  of 
secret  pricing. 

"Following  May  27,  1935,  deviations  from  published  prices  became  more  and 
more  troublesome.  By  August,  the  secret  prices  evidently  became  sufficiently 
serious  to  warrant  retaliation  by  the  price  leaders  in  the  industry.  Since  that 
time,  there  has  developed  one  of  the  worst  price  wars  experienced  in  recent  years 
by  this  industry.  Published  prices  remain  practicp.lly  the  same  as  they  were 
during  the  code  period,  but  discounts  and  rebates  ranging  from  20  to  30  percent 
are  being  granted  to  various  types  of  buyers." 

Despite  the  existence  of  this  price  war,  the  nominal  price  quotations     *     *     * 

showed  no  change  at  all  until  October  1935.     The  October  quotations  were  26 

cents,  or  10  percent,  below  the  September  prices;  but  even  this  reduction  in  the 

list  price  did  not  approximate  the  extent  of  the  discounts  which  were  being  granted. 

******* 

Frequently,  concessions  are  granted  more  indirectly.  For  example, 
advertising  allowances  are  a  common  form  of  granting  special  induce- 
ments to  purchasers.  Allowances  may  be  granted  for  window  display, 
preferred  location  of  goods,  use  of  special  selling  equipment,  adver- 
tising in  local  newspapers,  distribution  of  samples,  radio  advertising, 
the  furnishing  of  store  space  for  demonstrations,  and  the  like.  Sup- 
posedly the  allowance  is  proportioned  to  the  value  of  the  advertising 
services  so  rendered  to  the  manufacturer.  Frequently,  however,  par- 
ticularly prior  to  the  passage  of  the  Robinson-Patman  Act,  the  amount 
of  the  allowance  was  governed  largely  by  competitive  conditions  sur- 
rounding the  particular  transaction.  In  such  cases  the  advertising 
services  to  be  rendered  may  have  been  merely  the  excuse  for  the 
allowance;  often  no  eflfort  was  made  to  determine  whether  they  were 
actually  rendered  in  accordance  with  the  agreement.  Evidence  as 
to  the  extent  of  such  allowance  was  obtained  by  Congress  during  an 
investigation  of  the  American  Retail  Federation.^' 

Nor  are  practices  of  this  kind  confined  to  the  wholesale  market. 
Retailers  often  find  indirect  ways  of  granting  concessions,  to  customers 
when  overt  price  cuts  either  seem  impolitic  or  are  restrained  by  law. 
For  example,  a  retail  liquor  dealer  in  Washington,  D.  C,  carefully 
marks  all  his  merchandise  at  the  accepted  price  on  his  shelves  but 
allows  discounts  of  more  than  20  percent  to  any  customer  who  asks 
for  it.    In  a  southern  city  various  retail  druggists  who  depended  upon 

»'  Hearings  before  the  House  Committee  on  Investigation  of  the  American  Retail  Federation,  70th  Cong., 
Ist  sess.,  vol.  1,  pp.  465-470  and  vol.  4,  pp.  215-344. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  IQ^ 

price  appeal,  developed  a  novel  scheme  for  evading  minimum  prices 
established  by  contract  under  the  provisions  of  the  Fair  Trade  State 
Act.  They  sold  price-maintained  drugs  and  cosmetics  under  the 
installment  plan,  requiring  a  down  payment  of  a  specified  sum  some- 
what under  the  minimum  price,  with  the  balance  to  be  paid  subse- 
quently. It  is  possible  that  no  serious  effort  was  made  to  collect  this 
balance. 

Basically  the  issues  raised  by  this  section  may  be  summarized  in 
the  following  manner.  In  any  industry  or  trade,  unless  an  effective 
method  for  the  outright  allooation  of  business  exists,  there  will  be  a 
degree  of  rivalry  among  competitors,  each  seeking  to  expand  its  own 
share  of  the  market.  In  most  lines  the  competitive  strategy  best 
suited  to  the  position  of  the  rival  firms  will  show  some  variation 
between  them.  Usually,  some  firms,  such  as  the  largest  and  best 
known,  can  compete  more  effectively  on  the  basis  of  their  relative 
prestige.  Assuming  all  other  elements  of  the  transaction  to  be  iden- 
tical, a  constant  or  increasing  share  of  the  volume  would  naturally 
flow  to  them. 

Consequently,  those  firms  whose  prestige  is  inferior  usually  find  it 
necessary  to  offer  some  compensating  inducement.  The  most  obvious 
form  in  which  such  an  inducement  can  be  offered  is  as  an  outright 
price  reduction.  Frequently,  however,  the  possibility  of  using  price 
as  a  competitive  argument  is  limited  by  such  factors  as  the  fear  of 
reprisal,  the  threat  of  coercion,  or  the  operation  of  law.  In  ihat  case, 
competition  is  usually  diverted  into  other  channels. 

In  a  few  industries,  of  course,  all  members  are  apparently  content 
merely  to  maintain  their  respective  positions.  Whether  such  deci- 
sions be  voluntary  or  reflect  some  form  of  duress,  the  result  is  equiva- 
lent to  outright  monopoly.  In  most  industries,  however,  there  are  at 
least  some  firms  which  are  dissatisfied  with  their  shares  of  the  market. 
WTaenever  any  particular  form  of  competition  becomes  either  illegal, 
unprofitable,  or  for  any  reason  inexpedient,  other  outlets  for  the 
pressure  of  business  rivalry  are  devised  to  take  its  place  by  these 
aggressive  concerns.  The  range  of  such  devices  is  limited  only  by  the 
ingenuity  of  businessmen. 

This  protean  quality  of  competition  must  be  reckoned  with  in  any 
efforts  to  regulate  or  control  specific  competitive  practices.  When- 
ever any  one  avenue  of  competition  is  closed  or  made  difficult,  whether 
by  business  itself,  or  by  Government  through  such  legislation  as  the 
fair  trade  laws,  a  diversion  of  business  tactics  is  the  probable  result. 
Unfortunately,  as  indicated  in  the  following  section,  not  all  the 
aspects  which  competition  assumes  can  be  considered  equally  con- 
ducive to  the  efficient  functioning  of  the  economy. 

CONCLUSIONS 

In  summarizing  this  illustrative  discussion  of  phases  of  nonprice 
competition,  it  should  be  borne  in  mind  that  the  basic  criteria  upon 
which  public  policy  in  regard  to  business  practices  must  be  based  are 
their  effect  upon  the  standard  of  living  of  the  people,  and,  more 
broadly,  upon  the  manner  and  efficiency  with  which  the  Nation's 
economic  resources  are  utilized.  Uneconomical  or  wasteful  practices 
which  lead  to  unduly  high  prices  are  not  in  the  public  interest;  ob- 


JQ2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

souring  the  true  value  of  products  is  not  in  the  public  interest;  undue 
degradation  of  quality,  even  though  it  may  bring  lower  prices,  is  not 
in  the  public  interest.  All  of  these  practices  prevent  or  interfere  with 
the  best  use  of  the  consumer's  dollar  and  limit  his  standard  of  living. 
It  is  clear  from  the  discussion  presented  here  that  the  issues  involved 
in  regulation  of  business  practices  and,  in  particular,  of  the  trend 
away  from  price  competition,  are  exceedingly  complex.  This  report 
has  not  attempted  to  present  all  the  evidence  required  for  categorical 
judgment  on  the  value  of  these  various  forms  of  nonprice  competition; 
but  rather  to  suggest  where  the  weight  of  evidence  lies,  and  to  point 
to  possible  types  of  public  control. 

Attention  may  first  be  directed  to  the  escape  devices  discussed  in 
the  immediately  preceding  section.  The  evidence  seems  to  show  that 
in  many  industries  there  has  been  a  constant  redirection  of  competitive 
effort.  As  one  or  another  accepted  form  of  competition  becomes  il- 
legal or  inexpedient,  the  ingenuity  of  business  firms  is  exercised  in 
exploring  new  channels  to  replace  the  old  ones.  The  economic  effi- 
ciency of  this  process  seems  highly  dubious.  Its  general  trend  seems 
to  be  the  substitution  of  increasingly  indirect  ways  of  granting  con- 
cessions as  more  forthright  and  direct  ones  are  successively  abandoned. 
Indirection  is  not  generally  an  economical  or  efficient  process.  More- 
over, it  complicates  the  problems  of  choice  facing  the  buyer  in  com- 
-paring  the  offers  of  rival  sellers. 

It  has  been  shown  that  the  trend  frequently  reflects  the  efforts  of 
established  firms  to  maintain  their  position  in  an  industry  by  making 
it  difficult  for  new  entrants  to  compete  on  a  price  basis,  or  for  small 
and  comparatively  unknown  companies  to  expand  by  featuring  factors 
other  than  prestige  in  their  sales  strategy.  To  the  extent  to  which 
such  efforts  are  sucfcessful,  they  impair  the  desirable  flexibility  of 
business  structure.  Even  when  they  fail  in  their  ultimate  purpose, 
they  often  result  in  diverting  competitive  effort  from  direct  and  effi- 
cient channels  into  indirect  and  less  efficient  channels.  Public  policy 
may  therefore  be  properly  concerned  with  keeping  all  legitimate 
avenues  of  competition  equally  open,  and  with  discouraging  efforts  to 
bar  any  one  of  them. 

A  sharply  contrasting  situation  is  presented  by  such  conventional 
practices  as  "price  lining."  Price  lines  do  not  involve  any  constant, 
wasteful  redirection  of  competitive  effort.  Even  in  the  absence  of 
price  lines,  such  factors  as  quality  and  style  would  necessarily  play 
major  roles  in  the  apparel  market.  In  fact,  the  existence  of  price 
lines,  instead  of  complicating  the  problems  of  choice  facing  the  buyer, 
as  do  most  of  the  escape  devices  described,  actually  simplifies  them 
somewhat.  The  number  of  variables  between  rival  offers  is  reduced. 
The  buyer  can  accept  price  as  a  constant  and  concentrate  his  attention 
upon  comparing  other  elements  such  as  quality  or  style.  To  the 
seller  some  economy  is  achieved  in  the  problems  of  business  planning. 

On  the  other  hand,  there  seems  little  doubt  that  price  lining  incurs  a 
penalty,  particularly  when  the  lines  become  unduly  rigid.  The  ad- 
justments necessary  from  time  to  time  to  keep  a  product  within 
established  lines  may  be  wasteful  or  undesirable.  If  manufacturing 
costs  rise,  for  example,  quality  factors  may  be  seriously  skimped. 
When  costs  fall,  on  the  other  hand,  adjustment  may  take  the  form  of 
adding  unnecessary  frills  which  do  not  add  proportionately  either  to 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  103 

appearance  or  usefulness.  Such  developments  seem  inevitable  when 
production  is  geared  to  an  unchanging  price  pattern.  Considerations 
of  this  sort  apply  not  only  to  such  goods  as  apparel  but  with  f^qual  or 
greater  force  to  other  price-lined  articles  sucli  as  household  equipment 
(e.  g.,  radios,  washing  machines,  etc.). 

Moreover,  rigid  price  lining  may  detract  from  the  degree  of  price 
flexibility  which  is  economically  desirable.  This  is  particularly  true 
where  the  steps  between  successive  prices  are  large  and  where  the 
buyer  cannot  readUy  adjust  by  shifting  from  one  price  line  to  another. 
For  example,  during  a  period  of  declining  purchasing  power,  the  con- 
sumer may  be  obtaining  a  somewhat  superior  article  for  the  same 
price;  but  this  is  not  equivalent  in  its  economic  effect  to  a  direct  price 
reduction  for  an  article  of  unchanged  quality. 

It  cannot  be  gainsaid  that  there  is  a  certain  inevitability  about  the 
development  of  conventional  patterns  of  business  behavior.  Price 
lines  and  similar  customs  largely  reflect  the  adjustment  of  buyers  and 
sellers  to  each  others'  preferences  and  convenience.  Occasionally, 
the  rigid  maintenance  of  price  lines  may  be  associated  with  some  form 
of  concerted  or  collusive  action,  although,  in  the  main,  they  represent 
the  gradual  growth  of  custom  in  highly  competitive  industries,  where 
collusion  would  be  next  to  impossible. 

Consequently,  if  certain  aspects  of  conventional  business  practice 
were  found  undesirable  from  the  point  of  view  of  public  policy,  any 
program  of  action  would  have  to  take  lines  quite  different  from  those 
traditionally  followed  by  government.  A  mere  attack  upon  collusive 
practices  would  accomplish  little  or  nothing.  Instead,  any  revision 
of  business  habits  would  probably  have  to  proceed  from  a  general 
discussion  of  the  problem  and  mutual  agreement  within  the  industry 
as  to  the  desirable  modifications  of  conventional  patterns. 

So  much  for  the  more  general  problem.  It  now  becomes  pertin,ent 
to  consider  the  specific  issues  involved  in  the  several  major  forms  of 
nonprice  competition  which  have  been  described  above. 

One  of  the  most  important  and  difficult  issues  involved  is  the  net 
effect  of  the  emphasis  upon  quality  as  a  basis  for  competition.  It  is 
desirable  that  quality  be  good,  that  shoddmess  be  avoided;  but  at 
the  same  time  that  consumers  with  limited  incomes  have  available  a 
usable  article  priced  within  their  means  wherever  that  is  possible. 
It  is  reasonably  certain  that  the  recent  trend  away  from  price  com- 
petition has  materially  affected  the  character  of  the  goods  on  our 
markets  as  well  as  standard  of  living  of  consumers. 

In  some  ways  this  influence  has  been  undoubtedly  beneficial. 
Efforts  to  improve  quality  through  technical  research  and  otherwise 
have  been  stimulated.  This  is  notably  true  of  many  of  the  newer 
mass  production  industries  manufacturing  consumer  goods.  Thus, 
it  may  be  argued  that  the  automobile  is  today  a  far  more  satisfactory 
product  than  would  have  been  true  had  competition  focused  primarily 
on  price.  Data  have  been  cited  (see  pp.  63-67)  showing  that  improve- 
ments in  the  quality  of  such  products  as  automobiles,  refrigerators, 
tires,  etc.,  are  in  some  ways  equivalent  to  direct  price  reductions. 
The  benefit  which  the  consumer  derives  from  increased  economy  of 
operation  or  greater  durability  is  concrete  and  tangible;  sometimes 
it  may  be  translatable  into  direct  price  equivalents. 


247149— 41— No.  1- 


JQ4  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Conversely  there  is  some  evidence  to  show  that  where  the  price 
aspects  of  competition  are  strongly  stressed,  degradation  of  quality 
may  occasionally  follow.  If  price  cuttmg  is  the  niost  expedient  means 
of  expanding  sales,  producers  may  be  faced  with  the  necessity  of 
cutting  costs  correspondingly.  Sometimes,  of  course,  costs  may  be 
reduced  by  introducing  economies  of  operation  based  upon  improved 
technology,  but  this  is  not  always  feasible.  The  pressure  on  prices 
may  then  be  reflected  in  attempts  to  reduce  labor  costs  or  to  skimp 
on  quality.  The  latter  alternative  is  most  feasible  in  the  case  of 
articles  whose  quality  consumers  find  it  difficult  to  appraise,  as  where 
objective  standards  of  quality  are  unavailable  or  inadequate.  Nat- 
urally, this  tendency  becomes  aggravated  when  price  competition 
becomes  unusually  severe,  as  in  the  case  of  the  buyers'  market  pre- 
vailing during  a  depression.  National  Recovery  Administration 
experience  reveals  many  instances  of  this  situation." 

However,  the  reverse  side  to  this  picture  is  of  great  importance, 
particularly  to  consumers  of  limited  income.  Quality  features  have 
at  times  been  stressed  far  beyond  their  intrinsic  worth.  Unnecessary 
gadgets  and  eye-catching  features  have  been  multiplied.  Intensive 
selling  campaigns  have  been  conducted  to  persuade  consumers  to  de- 
mand such  features  in  place  of  price  reductions  which  could  have 

K  The  following  are  excerpted  from  a  study  prepared  by  the  Division  of  Review  of  the  National 
Recovery  Administration. 

(InfoTmation  Concerning  Commodities— A  Study  in  NRA  and  Related  Experiences  in  Control,  Part  B, 
Standards  and  Labeling.    By  Hunter  P.  Mulford,   Division  of  Review  Work  Materials,  No.  38.) 

Mayonnaise  Industry. — "At  the  time  of  the  sponsoring  of  its  code  the  industry  faced  a  difficult  situation, 
marked  by  severe,  price  competition,  which  was  felt  to  bear  particularly  heavily  upon  the  makers  of  higher 
grade  products.  Reduction  of  oil  content,  use  of  substitutes,  and  synthetics,  etc.,  were  among  the  means 
chiefly  employed  to  reduce  costs  and  increase  sales  volume  based  upon  low  price  appeal."  (Ibid.,  p.  18.) 
Preserve,  Maraschino  Cherry  and  Olace  Fruit  Industry.— "Duving  the  years  of  the  depression,  due  to  steadily 
increasing  price  competition,  a  decided  decline  in  the  Quality  of  the  industry's  products  occurred.  This 
was  a  natural  result  of  endeavoring  to  reduce  costs  and  by  so  doing  keep  selling  prices  at  a  fairly  low  level 
in  an  effort  to  either  retain  or  obtam  volume.  This  is  easily  understood  when  the  following  cost  figures  are 
considered.  At  2.5  cents  per  pound  for  fruit,  when  53  pounds  of  fruit  are  used  to  make  ICO  pounds  of  pure 
preserves,  the  cost  per  case  is  $1.33,  but  when  only  21  pounds  of  fruit  are  used  to  make  100  pounds  of  pre- 
serves, the  cost  "is  only  53  cents  per  case. 

"Therefore,  it  can  be  clearly  seen  that  by  reducing  the  amount  of  fruit  and  increasing  the  amount  of 
water,  plus  pectin,  considerable  savings  in  costs  can  be  made.  Industry  representatives  discussed  this  at 
considerable  length  at  the  public  hearing  on  their  code.  They  felt  that  this  lowering  of  quality  was  harmful 
to  the  industry  as  a  whole,  and  misleading  to  the  consumers."    (Ibid.,  p.  191.) 

Hosiery  Industry.— "This  depressed  condition  of  the  market  resulted  in  a  deterioration  in  the  quality  of 
hosiery  which,  because  of  the  nature  of  the  product,  can  readily  be  misrepresented.  Thus  Mr.  A.  Propper, 
executive  of  a  large  Chicago  department  store  stated: 

"  'Women's  hose  •  •  *  is  more  or  less  a  blind  article.  Any  manufacturer,  imknown  to  us,  or  any- 
body, can  easily  take  something  out  of  a  hose,  that  we  don't  know  has  been  taken  out  until  wo  find  •  *  ♦ 
that  something  has  marred  the  wearing  quality  of  the  hose.  Courses  can  be  dropped,  inferior  silk  can  be 
used,  threads  can  be  tightened,  and  other  small  manufacturing  qualities  that  are  not  discernible  to  the 
naked  eye  can  be  cheapened.' 

"Various  forms  of  quality  degradation  are  described  in  a  booklet  issued  by  a  manufacturer  of  unbranded 
hosiery  as  skimping  by  reducing  length;  reducing  number  of  stitches  in  the  seam;  use  of  lower-twist  thread; 
elimination  of  reinforcements;  insufBciont  number  of  courser-;  dropping  of  needles  in  the  knitting  bar;  old 
stock  sold  as  new;  failure  to  identify  fiber,  etc. 

"That  price  competition  had  induced  these  and  other  manipulations  in  quality  was  alleged.  To  quote 
again  from  Mr.  Propper's  speech: 

"  'We  nil  know  that  it  is  easy  to  cut  hosiery  down  to  a  price  »  •  •  that  is  aU  we  have  been  doing  In 
the  past,  cutting  it  down  to  a  price.'  "    (Ibid.,  p.  175.) 

Canning  Industry.— "Pressure  of  competition  within  the  industry  has  reduced  prices  in  recent  years, 
and  this  reduction  in  prices  has  in  turn  led  to  reductions  in  quality.  Prices  for  canned  goods  were  con- 
siderably lower  during  the  years  1932-34  than  for  some  years  previous,  and  during  this  later  period  some 
buyers  have  complained  that,  after  having  placed  contracts  for  future  delivery,  it  was  practically  impos- 
sible for  them  to  secure  merchandise  in  conformance  with  their  specifications."     (Ibid.,  p.  138.) 

Macaroni  Industry. — "Since  price  competition  had  become  so  acute  in  the  industry  in  the  last  year  and 
a  half,  manufacturers  felt  that  they  must  cut  the  cost  of  producing  their  goods  in  any  way  possible.  They 
could  not^cut  their  labor  costs  without  running  into  difficulties,  therefore  they  cut  the  cost  of  raw  materials. 
Consequently  there  has  been  a  great  increase  in  the  use  of  artificial  coloring  to  take  the  place  of  egg  content; 
there  has  also  been  increase  in  the  use  of  inferior  grades  of  flour  hi  place  of  higher  grade  semolina;  and  finally 
there  has  been  an  effort  to  use  a  mixture  of  soya  and  ordinary  flour  to  simulate  semolina."  (Ihid.,  p.  24.) 
Cleaning  and  Dyeing  Industry. — "Testimony  as  to  the  lowered  quality  of  services  which  accompanied 
price  competition  was  given  by  the  President  of  the  National  Association  of  Better  Business  Bureaus  (and 
by  others)  at  the  hearing  on  prices  and  code  violations  for  the  cleaning  and  dyeing  industry: 

"  'Our  files  show  that  refusal  to  adjust  complaints  is  in  the  majority  of  cases  excased  on  the  basis  that  at 
cut  rates  the  public  ain't  expect  service  or  responsibility. 

''  'From  the  consumers'  standpoint,  low  prices  have  resulted  in  unsatisfactory  cleaning  jobs  and  resulting 
«Jestruction  of  merchandise  at  a  very  alarming  rate.' "    (Ibid.,  p.  212.) 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  JQ5 

contributed  materially  to  making  available  a  larger  volume  of  goods 
to  the  consuming  public.  Where  cheeper  models  stripped  of  such 
features  have  been  introduced,  they  have  often  been  used  primarily 
as  leaders;  sales  effort  by  the  retailer  has  been  devoted  to  switching 
the  consumer  from  such  cheaper  models  to  more  expensive  ones 
carrying  luxury  features  of  doubtful  value. 

Sometimes  a  group  of  manufacturers  in  an  industry  makes  delib- 
erate efforts  to  establish  unnecessarily  high  standards  of  minimum 
quality.  By  precluding  the  appearance  of  low  grade,  though  satis- 
factory, merchandise  on  the  market,  they  hope  to  limit  the  scope  of 
price  competition.  On  the  other  hand  the  product  which  it  is  sought 
to  bar  may,  when  properly  used,  fill  a  perfectly  legitimate  need 
among  consumers  in  the  lower  income  brackets.  For  example,  certain 
members  of  the  plumbing  fixtures  industry  have  constantly  sought  to 
prevent  the  marketing  of  "culls"  or  "seconds"  as  a  means  of  protecting 
the  existing  price  structure.  These  efforts  were  the  subject  of  antitrust 
proceedings  by  the  Department  of  Justice.     According  to  the  Court: 

Defendants  (in  District  Court)  represent  the  Standard  (Standard  Sanitary 
Mfg.  Co.)  as  the  dominant  *  *  *  and  the  only  honest  manufacturer,  point- 
ing out  to  other  manufacturers  the  worthlessness  of  their  output,  they  not  having 
the  Arrott  patent;  also  the  dishonesty  of  *  *  *  putting  out  "seconds,"  the 
inferiority  of  which  was  discernible  only  by  experts  *  *  *  thereby  *  *  * 
"discrediting  the  ware  and  demoralizing  the  market  and  business."  To  avert  these 
evil  results  *  *  *  the  Standard  was  willing  to  forego  the  advantages  which 
its  ownership  of  the  Arrott  patent  gave  it  and  confer  them  upon  the  other  nianufac- 
turers.  But  upon  terms,  "First  and  foremost"  *  *  *  that  ng  "seconds" 
should  be  marketed. ^3 

Later,  there  was  an  endeavor  to  accomplish  this  same  purpose 
under  the  National  Recovery  Administration  by  prohibiting  the  sale  of 
culls  under  the  terms  of  the  Code.  According  to  a  National  Recov- 
ery Administration  study: 

Opposition  to  the  provision  was  voiced  by  several  smaller  manufacturers  on 
the  ground  that  certain  types  of  production  equipment  produced  a  larger  pro- 
portion of  culls;  that  to  prohibit  the  sale  of  culls  would  drive  such  plants  out  of 
business;  that  there  was  a  demand  for  this  grade  of  ware,  which  had  sound  utility; 
and  that  to  ban  it  would  increase  the  cost  of  plumbing  fixtures  to  the  public 
generally.     (Mulford,  op.  cit.,  p.  16.) 

Similarly,  the  bedding  industry  has  made  continual  efforts  to  pre- 
vent second-hand  materials  from  being  used  in  the  manufacture  of 
bedding  even  after  proper  sterilizatian.  In  a  few  States,  laws  to  this 
effect  were  enacted,  but  they  were  uniformly  held  unconstitutional 
on  the  grounds  that: 

The  business  here  involved  is  legitimate  and  useful;  and,  while  it  is  subject  to 
all  reasonable  regulations,  the  absolute  prohibition  of  the  use  of  shoddy  in  the 
manufacture  of  comfortables  is  purely  arbitrary  and  violates  the  due  process 
clause  of  the  fourteenth  amendment." 

Sometimes,  instead  of  attempts  to  bar  inferior  articles  from  the 
market  absolutely,  it  has  been  sought  so  to  stigmatize  them  as  to 
render  them  unsalable.  Thus  canners  unsuccessfully  urged  the  De- 
partment of  Agriculture  to  require  substandard  products  to  be  labeled 
in  such  a  manner  as  to  discourage  their  purchase. 

Excessive  emphasis  upon  price  competition,  then,  may  lead  to 
deterioration  of  quality;  undue  emphasis  upon  quality  may  result  in 
unwarranted  increases  in  price. 

"  Standard  Sanitary  Mfg.  Co.,  et  al.  v.  U.  S.  of  America  (226,  U.  S.  20). 
•<  Ibid.,  p.  29. 


JQg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

It  is  exceedingly  difficult  to  strike  a  balance  between  those  aspects 
of  quality  competition  which  may  be  considered  beneficial  and  those 
which  appear  detrimental  to  the  efficient  functioning  of  the  econom3^ 
Each  product  presents  a  different  situation.  The  line  between  the 
desirable  and  the  unnecessary  in  any  specific  case  is  one  which  must 
in  the  last  analysis  be  drawn  by  the  consumer.  It  is  appropriate, 
however,  for  Government  to  endeavor  to  devise  such  standards  and 
to  place  at  the  consumer's  disposal  such  technical  information  as  may 
make  it  possible  for  him  to  make  these  decisions  intelligently. 

Similar  conflicting  considerations  apply  to  the  second  broad  issue — 
the  competitive  emphasis  upon  brands,  trade-marks,  and  advertising. 
To  an  important  extent  such  devices  are  necessary  and  useful.  The 
creation  of  mass  demand  does  in  many  cases  pennit  the  introduction 
of  improved  methods  of  production  and  the  material  reduction  of 
manufacturing  costs.  It  is  probable  that  the  rapid  growth  of  the 
newer  mass-production  industries,  particularly  in  the  automotive  and 
the  electrical  household  equipment  fields,  has  been  facilitated  by  the 
intensive  use  of  advertising. 

Certainly,  too,  the  use  of  brands  and  trade-marks  to  distinguish  the 
product  of  rival  sellers  is  an  essentially  useful  technique,  both  to  the 
producer  who  has  acquired  a  deserved  prestige  and  to  the  consumer 
whose  problems  of  choice  are  facilitated. 

On  the  other  hand,  there  have  been  manifestations  of  growing  dis- 
satisfaction with  the  manner  in  which  brands  and  advertising  are 
used  today.  Consumers,  in  particular,  have  come  to  question  the 
reliability  of  the  guides  furnislied  them  by  advertising  and  branding. 
The  very  rapid  growth  of  the  organized  Consumer  movement  during 
recent  years  is  largely  a  reflection  of  this  dissatisfaction.  Business- 
men have  become  increasingly  concerned  with  this  reaction  of  con- 
sumers. The  proportions  and  significance  of  this  discontent  were  dis- 
cussed in  a  recent  issue  of  Business  Week: 

This  is  a  study  of  organized  discontent — the  discontent  of  some  consumers 
with  the  things  thej'  buy  and  the  way  those  things  are  sold  to  them.  It  is  a  dis- 
content which  feeds  upon  Uself  and  which  business  cannot  afford  to  overlook  be- 
cause it  has  already  assumed  the  proportions  of  a  real  threat  to  producers  and 
distributors  of  advertised  brands." 

Basically,  the  criticism  centers  about  the  failure  of  advertising  and 
branding  to  serve  as  adequate  guides  to  quality,  and  to  their  tendency 
to  divert  the  stream  of  competition  into  inefficient  channels.  While 
both  those  allegations  are  serious,  it  is  the  latter  which  is  of  primary 
importance  to  the  present  dibcussion,  and  with  which  public  policjT^  is 
concerned. 

It  has  been  pointed  out  that  one  efi'cct  of  the  creation  of  mass  de- 
mand through  advertising  may  be  the  reduction  of  costs  of  manufac- 
ture as  volume  increases.  On  the  other  hand,  it  must  be  conceded 
that  in  some  lines  of  business  any  such  reductions  in  cost  show  little 
if  any  tendency  to  become  translated  into  lower  prices.  Thus, 
according  to  Milton  Handler — 

It  cannot  be  denied  that  the  current  bewildering  use  of  brands  is  economically 
wasteful,  and  undoubtedly  tends  to  increase  the  costs  of  distribution.  The  tin- 
selled phrase  is  frequently  designed  to  camouflage  shoddiness  of  quality.  The 
fortunes  spent  on  popularizing  catch  words  and  nonsense  syllables  could  better 
be  devoted  to  the  improvement  of  product  and  the  dissemination  of  detailed  in- 

»»  Business  Week,  April  22,  1939,  p.  39. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  107 

formation  regarding  it,  which  is  so  essential  to  intelligent  consumption.  But  in- 
telligent consumption  also  requires  some  means  of  identifying  today  the  articles 
that  pleased  or  displeased  yesterday.  This  is  the  primary  function  of  the  mark. 
The  unfortunate  excrescences  of  modern  trade-mark  usage  should  not  blind  our 
perception  of  this  fact.^^ 

The  very  wide  spread  between  production  costs  and  retail  prices  for 
certain  common  drugs,  toiletries,  and  cosmetics  has  been  described. 
(See  pp.  80-83.)  This  spread  does  not  necessarily  represent  any  in- 
ordinate profits-  to  either  manufacturer  or  distributors;  much  of  it 
represents  the  cost  of  advertising  and  sales  campaigns  and  elaborate 
packaging.  Regardless  of  the  cause  for  the  spread,  however,  its 
existence  does  imply  the  possibility  of  greatly  reducing  the  prices  of 
products  of  this  kind  by  altering  the  focus  of  competition.  Such  a 
reduction  in  prices  would,  of  course,  be  equivalent  to  a  material  in- 
crease in  consumers'  purchasing  power  for  other  products. 

Here  again,  there  seems  sufficient  cause  for  public  concern  and 
proper  scope  for  pubhc  action.  The  development  of  adequate  com- 
modity standards  and  the  establishment  of  regulations  requiring 
informative  labeling  in  accordance  with  such  standards  would  go  far 
toward  fostering  the  desirable  and  discouraging  the  undesirable 
aspects  of  advertising  and  branding.  The  consumer  should  be  in  a 
position  to  appraise  the  significance  of  advertising  claims  and  of  brand 
names  against  a  background  of  authentic  product  information. 

In  summary,  it  seems  that  the  less  desirable  aspects  of  the  trend 
toward  competitive  reorientation  are  stimulated  by  at  least  two 
avoidable  conditions.  One  of  these  is  the  concerted  .or  collusive 
effort  of  certain  business  firms  to  prevent  the  use  of  sales  tactics 
which  they  deem  inexpedient.  The  second  is  the  inadequate  informa- 
tion of  most  consumers  with  regard  to  the  character  of  commodities 
offered  on  the  market.  Both  of  these  are  appropriate  subjects  of 
public  concern;  both  may,  to  an  extent,  yield  to  corrective  govern- 
mental measures. 

By  pursuing  its  traditional  policy  of  opposmg  collusive  action  by 
business  firms,  Government  may  ease  artificial  impediments  to  the 
use  of  socially  desirable  forms  of  competition,  particularly  of  price 
competition.  This  implies  also  that  individual  business  firms  must 
be  protected  in  their  freedom  to  choose  competitive  channels  from 
coercion  imposed  hj  their  rivals  who  prefer  that  such  channels  be  not 
used.  To  some  extent  this  pursuance  of  accepted  antitrust  policy 
may  also  serve  to  minimize  the  development  of  wasteful  escape 
devices  resulting  from  the  establishment  of  restraints  upon  one  or 
another  form  of  competition.  It  would  seem  highly  desirable  to 
consider  seriously  the  consequences  of  imposing  legal  restraints  upon 
the  direction  of  competitive  effort,  by  such  legislation  as  the  resale 
price  maintenance  acts  or  other  laws  seeking  to  restrict  price  com- 
petition. By  thus  endeavoring  to  keep  all  avenues  of  competition 
equally  open,  the  orientation  of  competitive  effort  may  be  determined 
more  by  the  combined  decisions  of  buyers  and  sellers  expressed  in  the 
market  place,  and  less  hj  the  monopolistic  determination  of  specific 
sellers. 

In  the  second  place.  Government  can  intensify  and  expand  its  pro- 
gram for  the  establislmaent  of  commodity  grades  and  standards  and 
its  requirements  as  to  informative  labeling.     Such  a  program  might 

w  Handler,  Milton,  Unfair  Competition,  Iowa  Law  Peview,  January  1936,  pp.  185-186. 


2Qg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

well  bo  coupled  with  a  broad  plan  for  consumer  education.  In  this 
way  the  consumer  v/ould  be  enabled  to  profit  by  the  trend  toward 
emphasis  upon  quaUty.  He  would  be  made  competent  to  judge  rival 
products  on  their  merits  instead  of  being  forced  to  rely  largely  upon 
claims  advanced  by  sellers.  The  accumulated  pressure  of  buyers 
equipped  with  an  adequate  basis  for  judgment  might,  in  turn,  serve 
to  direct  competition  into  socially  desirable  and  economically  efficient 
channels. 


CHAPTER  IV  ^ 

THE  ELECTRICAL  EQUIPMENT  INDUSTRIES— AN 
ILLUSTRATIVE  CASE 

SUMMARY 

So  far,  problems  of  price  and  sales  policy  have  been  considered  in 
a  broad  setting.  The  complexities  involved,  and  the  dangers  of  broad 
generalization  or  over-simple  solution  have  been  stressed. 

In  order  to  lend  concreteness  to  the  discussion  a  type  case  has 
been  selected  which  presents  in  specific  form  many  of  the  policy  issues 
encountered  in  the  preceding  analysis.  This  case  comprises  a  group  of 
industries  manufacturing  household  electrical  equipment,  such  as 
refrigerators,  washing  machines,  vacuum  cleaners,  etc. 

These  are  all  relatively  new  industries  which  have  experienced 
their  major  growth  during  the  past  two  decades.  A  number  of  them 
seem,  at  the  present  time,  to  have  entered  stages  in  their  development 
which  require  new  decisions  as  to  manufacturing  and  sales  policies. 
The  analysis  of  these  industries  contained  in  this  chapter  shows  that 
they  have  all  experienced  similar  patterns  of  growth.  First  is  the 
experimental  stage  during  which  the  product  is  being  developed. 
Many  crudities  are  still  apparent.  Costs  are  high  because  of  the  lack 
of  standardization,  coupled  with  a  low  aggregate  volume  of  output. 
Prices  are  correspondingly  high  and  sales  are  necessarily  confined  to  a 
limited  group  which  can  aft'ord  the  luxury  of  experimentation. 

This  period  merges  insensibly  in- vj  one  in  which  the  product  has 
become  relatively  satisfactory,  manufacturing  methods  have  become 
standardized,  and  prices  fall  in  anticipation  of,  and  partly  as  a  result 
of,  the  introduction  of  mass  production.  The  product  passes  out  of 
the  class  of  a  curiosity  and  obtains  a  wider  and  wider  general  appeal. 
Sales  expand  very  rapidly  as  more  and  more  consumers  realize  its 
convenience  or  desirability.  Usually  price  reductions  are  slightly 
ahead  of  sales  expansion.  During  this  phase  of  growth  the  expansion 
of  sales  seems  at  times  almost  limitless.  Even  the  depression  of  1930 
to  1933  exerted  no  more  than  a  very  limited  effect  upon  the  sales  of 
refrigerators  and  washing  machines.  By  the  fall  of  1933,  for  example, 
the  sales  of  washing  machines  were  exceeding  the  1929  rate  by  a 
substantial  margin.  During  such  a  period,  also,  as  profit  possibilities 
seem  very  attractive,  the  number  of  companies  in  the  field  often 
increases  sharply.  Eventually,  however,  signs  of  approaching  maturity 
become  apparent.  The  first  symptom  seems  to  be  an  arrest  in  the 
progressive  decline  in  costs  and  prices.  Then  the  rate  of  increase  of 
sales  begins  to  taper  off.  Distribution  of  the  product  among  families 
in  the  upper  and  middle  income  brackets  has  reached  a  high  level. 
The  number  of  remain ing  original  prospects  in  those  classes  dwindles 

'  Ch.  IV  was  prepared  by  Walt.    •  <. '«   im  anu  i  ihn  M.  Blair. 

109 


J  IQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

rapidly,  even  despite  the  constant  increase  in  the  number  of  wired 
homes,  particularly  in  rural  areas. 

At  this  point  the  industries  begin  to  display  very  marked  sensitivity 
to  changes  in  general  business  conditions.  Once  the  early  period  of 
dynamic  growth  has  passed,  they  are  no  longer  almost  depression-proof. 
The  durable  nature  of  the  product  involving  the  possibility  of  post- 
poning purchase  or  replacement  until  conditions  are  favorable  renders 
them  subject  to  extreme  cyclical  fluctuations.  For  example,  in  con- 
trast to  the  record  of  the  period  1929-1933,  the  number  of  washing 
machines  sold  fell  30  percent  from  1937  to  1938,  while  the  sales  of 
refrigerators  declined  more  than  45  percent.^  At  the  same  time, 
recovery  in  sales  volume  ha&been  longer  delayed  and  much  less  rapid. 

At  this  point,  then,  the  members  of  the  industry  are  faced  with  the 
urgent  need  of  reorienting  their  sales  policy  to  changing  conditions. 
Two  major  fields  for  sales  promotion  are  available.  One  of  these  is 
the  expansion  of  the  market  among  families  in  the  low-income  groups. 
The  other  is  the  development  of  the  replacement  market,  the  substi- 
tution of  new  equipment  for  outworn  or  obsolete  units.  The  tactics  to 
accomplish  these  ends  are  conditioned  by  many  other  market  factors 
such  as  the  rate  of  obsolescence  of  equipment,  the  channels  and  costs  of 
distribution,  the  possibilities  and  limitations  of  installment  selling, 
and  so  on. 

Until  1940  manufacturers  of  these  products  had  formulated  no  clear 
policy  to  meet  these  changing  conditions.  There  had  been  some  effort 
to  produce  cheap  "stripped"  models  devoid  of  all  luxury  features  to 
appeal  to  lower  income  groups.  There  had  been  a  few  scattered 
attempts  to  deal  with  the  replacement  problem.  Those  approaches, 
however,  seem  to  have  been  largely  exploratory. 

The  first  evidence  of  any  important  change  occurred  in  the  refrig- 
erator industry  during  the  early  months  of  1940.  During  the  second 
week  in  January,  one  manufacturer  announced  drastic  price  reductions 
for  its  6-foot  stripped  model  and"  its  competitors  immediately  followed 
its  lead.  At  the  same  time  economies  were  sought  in  the  costs  of  both 
manufacturing  and  distribution.  It  is  too  early  to  determine  whether 
these  moves  represent  a  true  change  in  long-term  policy,  or  whether 
they  merely  represent  a  temporary  "price  war"  touched  off  by  the 
action  of  a  single  manufacturer.  In  either  event  it  seems  significant 
that  sales  have  risen  sharply;  during  the  first  quarter  of  1940  they  were 
33  percent  higher  than  during  the  corresponding  months  of  1939. 

It  is  apparent  that  the  iormulation  of  sales  policies  designed  to 
exploit  the  potential  markets  of  these  industries  to  the  maximum 
involves  many  and  complex  issues.  The  nominal  price  alone  is  but 
one  of  these.  Methods  and  costs  of  distribution  must  be  subjected  to 
searching  analysis.  Decisions  musi  be  made  as  to  collateral  marketing 
poHcies.  The  treatment  of  used  equipment  is  a  basic  issue.  Another 
•of  major  importance  is  the  financing  of  conditional  sales.  More 
liberal  credit  terms  may  stimulate  the  market  immediately,  but  fail- 
ure to  maintain  sound  business  practices  in  the  process  incurs  a  sure 
penalty.  The  precise  balance  which  is  to  be  struck  between  improve- 
ments in  quaHty  and  reductions  in  price  is  of  prime  significance. 
Moreover,  all  of  these  decisions  must  be  adjusted  to  changes  in  general 

» This  (lifTerence  may  have  been  due  partly  to  the  fact  that  prices  were  reduced  during  the  forircr  but  not 
during  the  latter  period. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  m 

business  conditions  as  well  as  to  the  markets  for  the  specific  product 
in  question. 

The  problems  confronting  these  industries  are  typical,  in  many- 
ways,  of  those  encountered  in  many  other  industries  producing  con- 
sumers' durable  goods.  The  consumers'  durable  goods  industries 
have  played  a  particulariy  important  role  in  the  economy  of  the  last 
generation,  in  creating  opportunities  for  new  investment  and  employ- 
ment and  in  opening  new  horizons  for  consumer  enjoyment.  At  the 
same  time,  during  periods  of  business  recession,  the  drastic  contraction 
of  employment  and  investment  opportunities  to  which  these  industries 
are  generally  subject  creates  acute  social  and  economic  problems. 

The  manner  in  which  the  concerns  comprising  these  industries  adapt 
their  sales  policies  to  changing  market  conditions  will  largely  de- 
termine whether  they  will  expand  further,  remain  static,  or  decline. 
It  may  also  effect,  at  least  to  a  limited  extent,  the  stability  of  produc- 
tion during  the  swings  of  the  business  cycle. 

Consequently,  such  decisions  regarding  sales  policy  are  proper 
subjects  of  public  concern.  A  socially  and  economically  desirable 
policy  is  one  which  would  permit  the  widest  possible  distribution  of 
sales  so  that  more  consumers  may  have  the  benefit  of  these  products, 
afford  maximum  opportunities  for  employment  and  the  investment  of 
idle  funds,  and  achieve  a  degree  of  stability  adequate  to  minimize  the 
distress  attendant  upon  severe  cyclical  fluctuations.  The  orientation  of 
policy  to  attain  those  objectives  must  embrace  the  entire  problem; 
particularly  it  should  be  recognized  that  although  price  behavior  is 
important,  the  issues  far  transcend  the  field  of  price. 

Moreover,  it  should  be  emphasized  that  governmental  action  need 
not  be  regulatory  in  character.  Thus  the  Federal  Housing  Adminis- 
tration for  a  time  insured  loans  for  purchases  of  certain  types  of 
electrical  equipment  and  stimulated  sales  of  these  products.  The 
Electric  Home  and  Farm  Authority  has  also  assisted  -  in  financing 
sales  of  many  kinds  of  electrical  equipment;  in  the  process  it  encouraged 
the  production  of  relatively  inexpensive  models  to  meet  the  needs  of 
low  income  groups.  The  Rural  Electrification  Administration,  by 
widening  the  distribution  of  electric  power,  has  expanded  the  potential 
appliance  market.  Efforts  to  reduce  utility  rates  may  also  have  con- 
tributed materially  to  the  expansion  of  this  market. 

PRICE  AND  PRODUCTION  TRENDS 

The  growth  of  the  electrical-appliance  industries  during  the  past 
10  or  15  years  has  followed  a  pattern  which  is  typical  of  the  early 
stages  of  most  new  industries.  Rapid  technological  developments  and 
sharp  price  reductions  made  possible  mass  demand  and  the  economies 
of  mass  production.  The  following  tables  compare  the  average  retail 
values  of  refrigerators,  washing  machines,  vacuum  cleaners,  radios,  and 
electric  ranges  for  the  years  1929,  1932,  and  1937,  with  their  sales  dur- 
ing the  same  years.  Charts  XII  to  XV  show  the  trends  of  average 
retail  value  and  sales  for  these-products,  with  the  exception  of  radios, 
for  each  year  between  1927  and  1938.^ 

'  Average  unit  retail  value  was  selected  as  the  basis  for  this  analysis  instead  of  some  form  of  price  index 
for  two  reasons:  (1)  It  is  difficult  to  adjust  the  usual  type  of  price  index,  which  is  supposed  to  relate  to  a 
more  or  less  uniform  commodity,  to  the  very  rapid  changes  in  product  which  occurred  in  these  industries 
during  the  period  covered,  and  <2)  average  unit  value  figures  are  more  useful  because  they  portray  the 
average  outlay  by  the  consumer  for  the  commodities  involved. 


112 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


In  the  case  of  each  of  these  industries  the  period  of  most  marked 
price  decline  was  from  1927  to  1932,  whereas  the  period  of  most 
vigorous  sales  expansion  was  from  1932  to  1937.  Apparently  the 
stimulus  to  sales  caused  by  the  decline  in  prices  was  somewhat  delayed 
due  to  the  depression  from  1929  to  1932. 

Table  10. — Average  retail  value  and  sales  of  selected  electrical  appliances 
AVERAGE  RETAIL  VALUE 


1929 

1932 

1937 

Item 

Average 
retail 
value 

Index, 
1929=100 

Average 
retail 
value 

Index, 
1929=100 

Average 
retail 
value 

Index, 
1929=100 

$292 
113 
46 
133 
165 

100 
100 
100 
100 
100 

$195 
59 
35 
48 
150 

67 
52 
76 
30 
91 

$171 
72 
46 
56 
134 

59 

Washing  machines  -              .  .  

64 

100 

42 

Ranges                              ...      - 

81 

SALES 


Item 


Refrigerators.- 

Washing  machines 
Vacuum  cleaners— 

Radios 

Ranges 


Units 


778,000 

956, 000 

1, 395,  745 

4, 435, 000 

152,781 


Index, 
1929=100 


1932 


Units 


100  798, 000 
100  569, 830 
100  557, 288 
100  12,477,000 
100         60,000 


Index, 
1929=100 


103 
60 
40 
56 
39 


1937 


Units 


2,310,000 
1,  "-05,  405 
1,  706,  337 
6,  278,  267 
405, 000 


Index, 
1929=100 


297 
153 
122 
142 
265 


The  decline  in  average  unit  retail  value  in  these  industries,  in  gen- 
eral, ended  in  1932.  Between  1932  and  1939  average  unit  values  have 
shown  comparatively  little  change.  However,  sales  rose  sharply 
until  1937. 

In  the  case  of  electric  refrigerators,  for  example,  the  average  retail 
value  declined  from  $350  in  1927  to  $195  in  1932;  1  year  later  it 
fell  to  $170;  it  has  remained  near  that  figure  to  1938.  Sales  rose  from 
375,000  units  in  1927  to  778,000  in  1929.  The  increase  was  inter- 
rupted but  not  reversed  by  the  depression;  in  1932  sales  were  798,000 
or  slightly  more  than  in  1929.  During  the  subsequent  5  years  the 
expansion  was  resumed  even  more  vigorously;  in  1937  2,310,000  boxes 
were  sold. 

Similarly,  the  average  unit  value  of  washing  machines  fell  from  $143 
in  1927  to  $59  in  1932  and  remained  stable  at  about  the  latter  level 
until  1936.  In  1937  and  1938  the  average  value  rose  to  approximately 
$72.  Probably  this  last  increase  reflects  a  shift  in  buying  from 
cheaper  to  more  expensive  models  rather  than  any  change  in  prices  as 
such.  Sales  of  washing  machines  increased  slightly  from  1927  to 
1929,  then  declined  moderately  through  the  depression.  With  the 
first  signs  of  business  recovery,  however,  sales  expanded  sharply;  the 
1933  level  actually  exceeded  the  previous  peak  which  had  been 
reached  in  1929.  This  upward  trend  continued  to  a  maximum  of 
slightly  over  1,500,000  machines  sold  in  1936  in  contrast  to  the  pre- 
depression  peak  of  956,000. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chabt  XII 


113 


NUK.eER   SOLD 

THOUSANDS 

4000 


3000 


ELECTRIC    REFRIGERATORS 

NUMBER  SOLD  AND  RETAIL  VALUE 


1000 
900 
800 
70  0 
600 

500 
400 

300 


RETAIL    VALUE 
MILLIONS 
400 


UNIT  VALUE 
DOLLARS 
400 


1927     1928      1929     1930      1931       1932      1933      1934      1935     1936      1937      1938 

AVERAGE  REALIZATION  AT  RETAIL  AND 


100 
90 
80 
70 
60 

50 


30 


WHOLESALE  PRICE  INDEX 

1932  =  100 


300  - 


100 
90 
80 

70 


^REALIZATION' 


PRICE  INDEX 
400 


WHOLESALE  PRICE 


1927     1928      1929      1930     1931      1932     1933      1934      1935     1936     1937     1938 

(I)  SOURCE'  ELECTRICAL   MERCHANDISING 
U.S.  BUREAU  OF  LABOR  STATISTICS  


114 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chabt  XIII 


NUMBER  SOLO 
THOUSANDS  • 
2000 


ELECTRIC    WASHING    MACHINES 


NUMBER   SOLD  AND  RETAIL  VALUE 


1000 
900 
800 

700 

600 

500 


300 


RETAIL  VALUE 
MILLIONS 
200 


100 
90 
80 

70 

60 


40 


30 


1927      1928     1929      1930    1931       1932      1933     1934     1935     1936      1937     1938 

AVERAGE  REALIZATION  AT  RETAIL  AND 
UNIT  VALUE  WHOLESALE  PRICE    INDEX 


DOLLARS 
300 


100 
90 
80 
70 
60 


200 


PRICE  INDEX 
300 


'-REALIZATION' 


1927      1928      1929      1930      1931        1932      1933     1934     1935      1936     1937     1938 

(I)  SOURCE'  ELECTRICAL   MERCHANDISING 
US  BUREAU  OF  LABOR   STATISTICS 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chaet  XIV 


115 


NUMBER  SOLD 

THOUSANDS 

2000 


VACUUM   CLEANERS 

NUMBER  SOLD  AND  RETAIL  VALUE 


2  00 


100 


RETAIL  VALUE 
MILLIONS 
200 


100 
90 
80 
70 

60 

50 

40 
30 


20 


10 


1927     1928      1929.    1930     1931       1932     1933     1934      1935     1936     1937     1938 


UNIT  VALUE 

DOLLARS 
200 


100 
90 
80 
70 
60 


AVERAGE  REALIZATION  AT  RETAIL  AND 
WHOLESALE  PRICE  INDEX 

IS3ZM00 


30 


20 


WHOLESALE    PRICE 


PRICE     INDEX 
200 


J L 


J 1. 


100 
90 
80 
70 
60 


1927      1928     1929      1930     1931       1932      1933      1934     1935      1936     1937     1938 


(DSOURCE:  ELECTRICAL   MERCHANDISING 


30 


20 


116 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XV 


NUMBER  SOLD 
THOUSANDS 
600 


ELECTRIC    RANGES 

NUMBER  SOLD  AND   RETAIL  VALUE 


400 


100 
90 
80 
70 
60 


40 


RETAIL  VALUE 
MILLIONS 
60 


20 


927      1928     1929     1930     1931      1932      1933     1934     1935     1936     1937     193 

AVERAGE  REALIZATION  AT  RETAIL  AND 
uNiTVALUE  WHOLESALE  PRICE    INDEX 

IC32HOO 


DOLLARS 
200 


PRICE   INDEX 
200 


100 
90 


1927     1928     1929      1930     1931      1932     1933     19J4     1935     1936     1937     1938 

('1  SOURCE    ELECTRICAL    MERCHANDISING 
US  BUREAU  OF   LABOR  STATISTICS 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  117 

The  electric  range  industry  is  somewhat  younger  than  the  two 
previously  mentioned.  Presumably  reflecting  its  more  recent  growth, 
the  decline  in  unit  value  did  not  get  under  way  until  1931 ;  between  that 
3^ear  and  1935,  however,  there  was  a  material  fall  in  the  average  prices 
paid  by  consumers.  1937  sales  of  405,000  units  were  more  than  2}^ 
times  as  large  as  the  1929  peak  of  153,000  and  were  more  than  6  times 
as  great  as  the  1932  low  of  60,000. 

The  electric  vacuum  cleaner  industry  constitutes  a  possible  excep- 
tion to  the  pattern  described,  probably  because  it  is  slightly  older 
than  those  previously  considered  and  had  achieved  a  more  mature 
stage  of  development  prior  to  1927.  Nevertheless  the  all-time  sales 
peak  was  attained  in  1937.  The  average  retail  prices  of  vacuum 
cleaners  declined  from  $49  in  1927  to  $35  in  1932  and  then  rose, 
stabilizing  at  approximately  $45  for  the  years  1934-37.  This  rise 
probably  reflected  an  increase  in  the  proportion  of  the  higher-priced 
models  sold,  rather  than  any  change  in  price  as  such.  The  sales  of 
vacuum  cleaners  increased  from  558,000  units  in  1932  to  1,706,000 
in  1937. 

Taken  as  a  whole  the  price  and  sales  behavior  of  these  new  indus- 
tries manifest  three  basic  common  characteristics: 

(1)  A  marked  decline  in  price  between  1927  and  1932. 

(2)  A  relative  stabilization  of  price  near  the  low  level  reached  in 
1932. 

(3)  A  great  increase  in  sales  during  the  period  1932-37. 

To  these  three  characteristics  may  be  added  a  fourth.  In  each  case 
there  was  an  abrupt  decline  in  sales  during  the  "recession"  of  1937-38. 
During  this  period  electric  refrigerator  sales  declined  by  46  percent, 
electric  washing  machines  by  30  percent,  vacuum  cleaners  by  24  per- 
cent, and  electric  ranges  by  38  percent. 

These  declines  came  immediately  after  each  of  these  industries  had 
reached  a  sales  volume  never  before  attained.  Presumably  they 
reflected  basic  changes  in  market  conditions.  An  important  factor 
is  probably  market  "saturation." 

MARKET    SATURATION 

For  the  electrical  appliance  industries,  market  saturation  may  be 
measured  in  terms  of  the  proportion  of  homes  wired  for  electricity  in 
which  these  appliances  are  installed.  In  appraising  the  significance 
of  this  measure,  it  is  important  to  remember  that  the  number  of 
wired  homes  is  continually  increasing,  both  as  new  homes  are  built 
and  as  the  use  of  electric  power  is  extended.  This  is  particularly 
true  in  rural  areas,  partially  due  to  the  activities  of  such  government 
agencies  as  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority  and  the  Rural  Electri- 
fication Administration.  (The  significance  of  these  programs  in 
creating  new  markets  for  electrical  appliances  is  discussed  below — 
pp.  158-160.)  Since  the  number  of  potential  consumers  is  thus 
growing,  the  degree  of  saturation  in  terms  of  wired  homes  prevailing 
at  any  time  should  not  be  construed  as  setting  any  fixed  limit  to  the 
available  market  for  original  sales.  Nevertheless,  this  measure  does 
afford  an  indication  of  the  potential  market  available  at  any  given 
time,  and  the  rapid  increase  in  the  percentage  of  saturation  for  many 
of  these  appliances  shows  that  the  market  for  original  sales  is  steadily 
dwindling  despite  the  increasing  availability  of  electric  power.     At 


118 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


the  same  time,  the  figures  also  show  that  complete  saturation  has 
not  even  been  approached  for  any  of  these  appliances;  a  substantial 
original  market  remains  whose  effective  development  obviously  de- 
pends upon  the  sales  policies  adopted  by  manufacturers. 

The  trend  of  market  saturation  from  1925  through  1937,  measured 
in  this  way,  for  electric  refrigerators,  electric  washing  machines, 
.electric  vacuum  cleaners,  and  electric  ranges  is  shown  in  chart  XVI 
and  in  the  following  table: 

Table  11. — Saturation  of  the  market 


Percentage  of  wired  liomes  owning— 

Year 

Refrig- 
erators 

Washing 
machines 

Vacuum 
cleaners 

Ranges 

1925                        - 

(') 

2 

4 

6 

9 

13 

17 

22 

25 

29 

34 

41 

49 

62 

21 
27 
28 
30 
33 
35 
41 
39 
44 
46 
49 
53 
5« 
58 

31 

37 
39 
41 
44 
44 
45 
47 
49 
48 
48 
49 
49 
49 

3 

1926      - -- 

3 

1927                     .       .       .  1 

3 

1928      - 

4 

1929 -.- 

4 

1930 

5 

1931        

5 

1932 

6 

1933                    - 

6 

1934 

6 

1936                                .                ..              

7 

1936              - --- 

8 

1937 

9 

1938 

10 

1 

'  Less  than  1  percent. 

For  electric  refrigerators,  electric  washers,  and  electric  ranges  the 
degree  of  saturation  has  steadily  increased,  especially  during  the 
period  1932-37.  The  vacuum  cleaner  market,  on  the  other  hand, 
has  not  experienced  such  a  sharp  increase  during  recent  years  because 
it  was  already  saturated  to  a  much  higher  degree,  than  were  any  of 
the  other  fields  at  the  beginning  of  the  decade. 

A  comparison  of  saturation  in  each  of  the  industries  with  the  ex- 
tent of  sales  decline  during  two  periods  of  business  recession  is  pre- 
sented in  the  following  table.  Saturation  in  1929  is  shown  in  relation 
to  the  change  in  sales  between  1929  and  the  depression  years  1932-33,* 
and  saturation  in  1937  is  compared  with  the  sales  decline  between 
1937-38. 

Table  12. — Market  saturation  and  sales 


Item 

Percent 

saturation 

1929' 

Percent  change 

in  number  sold 

1929  to  average 

1932-33 

Percent 

saturation 

1937 

Percent  change 

in  number  sold 

1937-38 

Refrigerators 

9 
33 
44 

-f  17                         49 
-20                           50 
—54                            4Q 

-46 

Washing  machines 

-30 

Vacuum  cleaners 

—24 

'  Percent  of  wired  homes. 
Source:  Electrical  Merchandising. 


*  The  1932-33  average  was  considered  to  give  a  better  measure  of  dciJiossion  decline  than  either  of  the.'^e 
years  taken  separately.  For  refrigerators  and  washing  macliinos  1932  sales  showed  a  drop  which  was 
somewhat  extreme.  On  the  other  hand,  1933  sales  for  both  of  these  industries  showed  a  very  sharp  revival. 
Consequently,  tho  two  were  averaged  to  obtain  r.  more  eenorally  representative  figure. 


CONCENTPATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


119 


O   — uj  m 


<a: 
ecu 
30- 


< 

I- 
< 
CO 


\ 

\ 

( 

1 

\ 

z 
o 

If 

^ 

UJ 

_l 
< 

\ 

i 

1 

Qlui 
30- 


^; 

zll 
ol 

3  1 

1 

-IqO 


-ISO 


CO 
LJ 

< 
CO 


^ 

o 

a: 

\ 

\ 

/ 

.       in 

%        UJ 

\    _i 
\   < 

\| 

■ 

1- 
< 

> 

\ 

\ 

\ 

uluj 

30. 

1 

i 

CO 

■ 

<o 

\ 

- 

rr 

ll  z 

\ 

III 

y  2 

\ 

■z 

1  < 

\ 

< 

(£ 

% 

UJ 

H 

\ 

1 

< 

1 

o 

Vi' 

I 

s 

\ 

to 

) 

3 

\ 

UJ 

/ 

_) 

1 

< 

/ 

o 

n 

""J      1 

< 

H 

\l      1 

> 

y 

\ 

\ 

1 

. 

a 

UJ30 
-lOO 


247149— 41— No.  1- 


-10 


]^20  CONCENTRATION  OF  iX^ONOMIC  POWER 

For  refrigerators  a  sharp  drop  in  sales  between  1937  and  1938  con- 
trasted with  an  actual  increase  between  1929  and  1932-33.  In  the 
case  of  washing  machines  there  were  declines  during  both  periods, 
but  that  between  1937  and  1938  was  materially  greater  although  the 
recession  in  general  business  Activity  was  much  less  prolonged. 
Between  1929  and  1937,  however,  the  degree  of  saturation  for  re- 
frigerators had  increased  fivefold,  and  for  washing  machines  it  had 
almost  doubled.  The  sharpest  difference  in  the  trend  of  sales  oc- 
curred in  electric  refrigerators  in  which  the  change  in  saturation  was 
most  marked. 

The  sales  of  vacuum  cleaners  declined  much  more  severly  during 
the  1929-33  depression  than  did  those  of  either  refrigerators  or 
washing  machines.  At  the  same  time  the  degree  of  saturation  for 
this  product  was  materially  higher  than  for  either  of  the  other  two.* 

Apparently,  therefore,  the  change  in  the  character  of  the  market  is 
largely  responsible  for  the  change  in  the  sensitivity  of  these  industries 
to  depression  influences.  As  long  as  there  is  a  wide  market  for 
original  sales,  declines  in  the  rate  of  general  business  activity  seem 
to  retard  growth  somewhat,  but  do  not  result  in  severe  contractions 
of  sales.  As  the  original  market  becomes  more  nearly  saturated, 
however,  the  picture  changes.  This  is  probably  true  particularly  of 
that  segment  of  the  market  which  involves  the  replacement  of  used 
equipment,  since  replacements  are  usually  postponed  during  periods 
01  general  economic  stress.  Consequently,  the  exploitation  of  the 
original  market,  coupled  with  the  tendency  of  consumers  to  postpone 
replacements  during  periods  of  bad  business,  results  in  making  in- 
dustries of  this  land  increasingly  sensitive  to  depression  influences  as 
the  degree  of  market  saturation  increases. 

Saturation  by  income  groups. — Market  saturation  is  particularly 
significant  in  relation  to  income  groups,  since  it  reveals  the  particular 
segments  of  the  market  which  constitute  the  most  favorable  prospects 
for  "new"  sales. 

A  study  of  consumer  purchases  ^  by  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics 
in  1935-36  shows  the  distribution  of  ownership  of  electric  refrigerators, 
washing  machines,  vacuum  cleaners,  and  radios,^  by  various  income 
groups.*  This  survey  covered  a  representative  sample  group  of 
Tamilies  restricted,  in  this  case,  to  urban- areas  and  to  families  whose 
heads  were  native-born  and  of  native  parentage.  These  data,  as 
presented  in  charts  XVII  to  XX  inclusive,  give  an  approximate  indica- 
tion of  market  saturation  for  this  specific  sector  of  the  population 
and  may  also  afford  some  guide  to  conditions  prevailing  in  the  market 
as  a  whole. 

The  charts  compare  the  degree  of  saturation  (i.  e.,  the  percentage 
of  families  having  these  appliances  in  each  income  group)  for  these 
products  in  selected  cities  in  six  areas  of  the  country.     The  patterns 

»  Electric  ranges  have  been  omitted  from  this  discussion.  Although  saturation  as  measured  by  wired 
homes  undoubtedly  affects  their  sale,  this  effect  is  probably  overshadowed  by  the  influence  of  the  rate  of 
new-home  construction.  It  may  even  be  contended  that  new-home  construction  constitutes  almost  the 
entire  true  "original"  market  for  electric  ranges;  that  the  substitution  of  an  electric  range  for  a  used  gas 
or  coal  range  la  largely  in  the  nature  of  a  replacement  sale. 

•  The  Study  of  Consumer  Purchases,  in  which  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  and  the  Bureau  of  Home 
Economics  have  cooperated  with  the  National  Resources  Committee,  the  Central  Statistical  Board,  and 
the  Works  Progress  Administration,  provides  data  on  the  average  purchases  of  families,  including  husband 
and  wife,  both  native-born,  at  different  income  levels,  in  cities  in  different  parts  of  the  country  for  the  year 
1935-36. 

'  The  radio  data  are  presented  to  illustrate  an  industry  whose  market  is  almost  completely  saturated. 

•  This  study  of  consumer  expenditures  reifttes  to  nonrellef  families  including  husband  and  wife,  both 
native-born,  in  18  url>an  areas  throughout  the  country. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         121 

for  refrigerators  and  vacuum  cleaners  are  similar,  with  a  rapid  and 
progressive  increase  of  saturation  as  income  rises.  In  the  case  of 
radios,  saturation  is  almost  complete  at  a  relatively  low  income  level. 
Washing  machine  ownership  presents  a  contrast;  there  is  a  rise  in  the 
rate  of  ownership  until  the  $1,250-$1,500  income  class  is  reached,  but 
higher  income  brackets  show  little  if  any  further  increase.  This 
probably  represents  the  greater  tendency  of  upper  income  groups  to 
send  laundry  to  commercial  laundries. 

Chart  XVII  presents  o^\^lership  data  for  electric  refrigerators  in 
more  detail.  The  pattern  is  generally  consistent;  in  each  case  sat- 
uration increases  rapidly  with  income.  The  lower  income  groups 
have  not  been  reached  effectively  while,  in  general,  the  market  among 
the  upper  groups  is  almost  completely  saturated. 

The  two  "metropolises"  (i.  e.,  New  York  and  Chicago)  present 
exceptions  to  this  pattern;  the  curve  flattens  out  in  the  middle  and 
upper  income  groups.  These  exceptions  can  be  explained  by  the 
large  number  of  such  families  living  in  apartment  houses  in  which 
refrigerators  or  refrigeration  are  furnished  by  the  landlord.  Although 
this  practice  is  most  marked  in  these  two  areas,  it  is  not  confined  to 
them.  In  interpreting  these  figures,  therefore,  it  should  be  recog- 
luzed  that  in  general  the  percentage  of  families  in  the  middle  and 
upper  income  levels  using  electric  refrigerators  is  greater  than  the 
percentage  owTiing  them. 

The  rapid  increase  in  the  proportion  of  families  owning  this  equip- 
ment as  income  rises,  as  shown  by  the  steepness  of  the  curves  for  all 
areas,  indicates  that  future  sales  to  the  upper  and  upper  middle  income 
groups  must  be  largely  for  replacement,  and  that  the  major  potential 
market  for  original  sales  is  to  be  found  among  families  with  lower 
incomes. 

In  1935-36  only  17  out  of  100  homes  having  incomes  of  less  than 
$1,500  reported  ownership  of  electric  refrigerators.  The  market  in 
the  middle-income  groups,  $l,500-$3,000,  was  approximately  54  per- 
cent saturated  while,  for  families  with  incomes  of  $3,000  and  over, 
the  ratio  was  80  percent. 

For  vacuum  cleaners  the  saturation  pattern  is  simdar  to  that  of 
electric  refrigerators.  Saturation  increases  rapidly  as  income  rises; 
29  percent  of  the  families  in  the  $250  to  $1,500  income  groups  own 
cleaners;  for  the  middle  income  group  the  figure  is  71  percent;  for  the 
upper  group  it  is  90  percent. 

In  the  case  of  radios  it  is  apparent  that  saturation  is  practically 
complete  for  all  income  groups  except  the  very  lowest;  the  radio  market 
is  therefore  almost  entirely  on  a  replacement  basis  or  on  a  basis  of 
selling  extra  radios  for  other  rooms  in  the  home. 

The  charts  also  show  certain  geographical  differences.  The  market 
saturation  curve  for  most  items  is  lower  in  the  Southeast  even  among 
white  families  than  in  the  other  areas.  This  is  particularly  true  of 
washing  machines  and  vacuum  cleaners.  In  the  case  of  electric  re- 
frigerators, the  contrast  is  not  so  great,  probably  because  of  climate. 

In  most  areas,  the  saturation  curve  for  large  cities  is  slightly  above 
the  curves  for  small  cities.  Finally,  for  each  of  the  items,  the  satura- 
tion curves  for  small  cities,  middle-sized  cities,  and  large  cities  display 
a  surprising  degree  of  uniformity;  that  is,  there  is  the  same  general 


122 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chabt  XVII 


HOUSEHOLD  EQUIPMENT  OWNERSHIP  BY  INCOME  GROUPS 

ELECTRIC    REFRIGERATORS 

1935-36 

NON-RELIEF   FAMILIES   INCLUDING   HUSBAND 
AND  WIFE  BOTH  NATIVE   BORN 


PCRCEHl 

NEW  ENGLAND 

PER 

eo 

r 

-^ 

^ 

0 

A. 

^^^ 

^--^'^-^ 

-=^ 

40 

fl 

i 

/ 

V 

^ 

V 

i 

/s 

^- 

20 
0 

/'f^\ 

J 

C 

^ 

„,*-— "^ 

V^ 

s 

L. 

^ 

U 

0^ 

^ 

^-^ 

^V 

^ 

EAST  CENTRAL 


eo 


1 

A =5.^—= 

1       /^ 

K 

1    ^-^ 

\  £/ 

^ 

S^ 

1 

^ 

-^ — ^ 

-L^         4-L- 

... .. 

WEST  CENTRAL 


80 


250        1000  2000  3000  4000  5000 

INCOME  GROUPS  IN  DOLLARS 

^^  METROPOLIS             ►♦^^  MIDDLE-SIZED  CITIES 
"=•  LARGE  CITY               ooooo  SMALL  CITIES 
US  mWC*U  or  LABOR  STATISTICS  |STUOt  OF  CONSUMER  PURCHASES.  URBAN  SERIES 


80 


20 


rp^ 

C^]^__ 

—  ■ 

100 

r 

y 

9 

^ 

^ 

60 
40 
20 
0 

^ 

1 

i 

/ 

= 

J 

i 

- 

V 

t 

4 

1 

rSOO  AND  OVER 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Ohabt  XVII— Continued 


123 


HOUSEHOLD  EQUIPMENT  OWNERSHIP  BY  INCOME  GROUPS 

ELECTRIC    REFRIGERATORS 

1935-36 

NON   RELIEF   FAMILIES    INCLUDING  HUSBAND 
AND  WIFE  BOTH  NATIVE  BORN 


PERCENT 
100 


80 


20 


40 


20 


SOUTHEAST 


ROCKY   MOUNTAIN 


PACIFIC  NORTHWEST 


250      1000         2000         3000        4000        5000  7500 

INCOME  GROUPS  IN  DOLLARS 

— =»  LARGE  CITY 

•♦■♦^  MIDOLE-SIZEO  CITIES 

U^S  ■UWtAUJjMJjOjjl   »T«TISTIC»;  STUDY  Of  COWaUMIW  jUjlCH*M«, jjWMiM   ^flMM 


r^ 

>^ 

» 

fr 

^ 

« 

c 

^ 

I 

^ 

^ 

1 

i 

A 

f 

i 

9 

H 

H 

— M — ■ — 1/-^ 


10,000 

MPOVtH 


T500  *Np  even 


124 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chabt  XVIII 


HOUSEHOLD  EQUIPMENT  OWNERSHIP  BY  INCOME  GROUPS 

POWER  WASHING  MACHINES 

1935-36 

NON-RELIEF    FAMILIES    INCLUDING    HUSBAND 
AND  WIFE  BOTH  NATIVE    BORN 

PCRCENT                                                                                        NEW      ENGLAND                                                                                        PERCCNT 

80  - 
60  - 

40  - 

c 
20  - 

80 

60 

40 

20 

0 

100 

80 

60 

40 

20 

*" 

i 

r 

A. 

yxxi 

,00 

i 

ft 

v^ 

...— ' 

^^ 

\ 

y^ 

"*- 

^ 

A=* 

^^ 

- 

" 

\ 

^^"^u-r^  r^ 

EAST 

CENTRAL 

80  - 
60  - 
40  - 
20 

p 

^3^ 

/^ 

f  ^ 

^ 

1 

^1 

•eS 

k:> 

x^--^ 

*L 

r 

^ 

^ 

•^ 

-^-^ 

WEST 

CENTRAL 

100 
80 
60 
40 
20 

80 
60 
40 
20 

,,, 

^ 

r^ 

% 

^ 

< 

^ 

-N 

. 

"XT^ 

i 

v- 

""•^ 

1 

°2 

V)  8.1 

0    lob 
\iM*u  a 

0        2000        30'00        4000        5000                                 75 
INCOME  GROUPS   IN  DOLLARS 

— •  METROPOLIS                •****  MIDDLE-SIZED 
— =•  LARGE   CITY               .««o«  SMALL  CITIES 
r  LABOM  STATOTICSi  STUDY  OT  CONSUUER  PURCHASES,  URBAN  SERIES 

00                                iO.C 
:iTIES 

•7500 « 

0( 

MO 

) 

n 

OVER 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XVIII— Continued 


125 


HOUSEHOLD  EQUIPMENT  OWNERSHIP  BY  INCOME  GROUPS 

POWER  WASHING  MACHINES 

I93S-36 

NON-RELIEF    FAMILIES    INCLUDING   HUSBAND 
AND  WIFE  BOTH  NATIVE   BORN 


PERCENT 
100 


SOUTHEAST 


40 


PERCENT 
100 


40 


PERCENT 
100 


ROCKY   MOUNTAIN 


PACIFIC  NORTHWEST 


250      1000         2000        3000        4000        5000  7500 

INCOME  GROUPS  IN  DOLLARS 

— =»  LARGE  CITY 
•♦♦^  MIDDLE-SIZED  CITIES 
u  ».  tunw  Of  iMon  groTtmcSi  stupy  or  comuMCw  puwcm*sc»,  umah  stmts 


_^__ 

, 

80 
60 

40 

- 

/ 

/^ 

V 

::^ 

«^ 

c 

^"'" 

J 

/ 

/ 

r 

/ 

/ 

20 

0 

•7900  *N00yW_ 


126 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Ohabt  XIX 


HOUSEHOLD  EQUIPMENT  OWNERSHIP  BY  INCOME  GROUPS 

VACUUM  CLEANERS 

1935-36 

NON   RELIEF   FAMILIES    INCLUDING   HUSBAND 
AND  WIFE  BOTH  NATIVE   BORN 


PERCENT 

too 


eo 


40 


20 


20 


100 


60 


NEW   ENGLAND 


EAST  CENTRAL 


WEST  CENTRAL 


250     1000         2000        3000        4000        5000 

INCOME  GROUPS  IN  DOLLARS 

«—  METRQPLIS 
— =-  LARGE  CITY 


7500 


MIDDLE-SIZED  CITIES 
<«>*»«  SMALL  CITIES 


i 

^ 

^.yi 

^ 

^1  !  msi            ^ 

^  jp-r^^ 

^^ 

^   . 

■  —      ■ 

k 

i 

r 

v 

> 

k 

1 

1 

r 

k 

\ 

/ 

- 

J 

Li 

J 

1 — ' 

PERCENT 
100 


80 


20 


60 


40 


20 


"■[    ■■  ■  ■■  ■          — — ' 

1 — 1 

^^^^ 

SSS^-.-— 

""^^ 

y^\ 

At 

U   t.WRIAU  Of  L«tOW  tTATI»TIC«;  8TUDY  OF  COWSUMIR   PURCHAglR.  URB*N  MRItS 


10,000 
ANO  OVER 


7S00  AND  OvtR 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XIX — Continued 


127 


HOUSEHOLD  EQUIPMENT  OWNERSHIP  BY  INCOME  GROUPS 

VACUUM   CLEANERS 

1935-36 

NON-RELIEF  FAMILIES   INCLUDING   HUSBAND 
AND  WIFE  BOTH  NATIVE   BORN 


KRCENT 
100 


60 


40 


SOUTHEAST 


^^^^___^» 

r 

***. 

H^^^'^ 

^ 

Vy 

..^ 

\ 

— ' 

ROCKY  MOUNTAIN 


PACIFIC  NORTHWEST 


250      1000         2000        3000        4000        5000  7500 

INCOME  GROUPS  IN  DOLLARS 

•=»  LARGE  CITY 

•*•**  MIDDLE-SIZED  CITIES 

U  ».  lUMM)  OF  U»OW  ITgmTIMi  tTUOY  Or  COW«uytR  Pm>CM*«E». URBAN  StHH« 


100 

-•w 

IOC 

^ 

1^ 

!^^»^ 

==»----—  —  —"■ " 

60 

40 

20 

0 

/ 

/ 

? 

4 

9 

60 
40 
20 
0 

J 

f 

/ 

- 

* 

} 

^ 

V 

I 

- 

_ 



U 

}P^^ 

""^^ 

jM 

V 

¥ 

1 0,000 

AND  OVER 


*7500  AWOfVew 


128 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chabt  XX 


HOUSEHOLD  EQUIPMENT  OWNERSHIP  BY  INCOME  GROUPS 

RADIOS 
1935-36 

NON-RELIEF   FAMILIES   INCLUDING   HUSBAND 
AND  WIFE  BOTH  NATIVE  BORN 


40 


NEW  ENGLAND 


EAST   CENTRAL 


WEST    CENTRAL 


250      1000         2000        3000        4000        5000  7500 

INCOME  GROUPS  IN  DOLLARS 


•^—  METROPOLIS  MIDDLE-SIZED  CITIES 

-c=«  LARGE  CITIES  <><kxx>  SMALL  CITIES 

U   3   BUREAU   OF  LABOR  STATISTICS,  STUDY   OF  CONSUMER  PURCHASES,  URBAN   SEBICS 


PERCENT 
100 


• 

f 

f 

¥^ 

^ 

iMi 

iOft 

*** 

==*•« 

.10,000 

AND  OVER 


7500   AND  OVER 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chabt  XX — Continued 


129 


HOUSEHOLD  EQUIPMENT  OWNERSHIP  BY  INCOME  GROUPS 

RADIOS 
1935-36 

NON-RELIEF   FAMILIES   INCLUDING   HUSBAND 
AND  WIFE  BOTH  NATIVE    BORN 

PERCENT                                                    SOUTHEAST                                                   percent 
100 -»- — — — — — -  »^n  tT»^ '■ , , — .ino 

80 
60 
40 
20 

0 

100 

"/ 

/ 

t 

;■ 

c5 

^ 

A 

" 

^^ 

pn*- 

-  80 

-  60 

-  40 

-  20 

i 

f 

f 

r 

ROCKY   MOUNTAIN 

-ilOO 

-  80 

-  60 

-  40 

-  20 

■  0 
100 
80 
60 
40 
20 

80 
60 
40 
20 

0 

i 

f 

i^ 

^ 

^ 

7     " 

^ 

«=:*• 

^=^" 

^^ 

f 

— '       1          1          1          1                        1               ■ ' '       1 

PACIFIC  NORTHWEST 

80 
60 
40 
20 

\ 

V 

f 

^ 

^ 

^ 

w 

^ 

!»^ 

iSr-* 

-=*. 



'^^ 

2 

U.S. 

50      lobo         20'00        3000        40 
IN 

■UREAU  OF  LABOR  STATISTICS;  STUDY  OF  C0< 

00        50 
COME  GRC 

=»  LARGt 
►^MIDDL 

4SUMCR  PUR 

00                                  75 
UPS  IN  DOLLARS 

:  CITY 
E-SIZEO  CITIES 

CHASES,  URIAH  ICRIIS 

00                                   10,0 
ANDC 

•7500  AND 

00 
)VER 

OVEH 

130 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


tendency  for  a  larger  share  of  families  in  upper  income  groups  to  own 
electrical  appliances  in  all  communities. 

Expenditures  by  families. — During  the  period  of  general  business 
revival  in  1934-36,  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  conducted  a  study 
of  actual  expenditures  for  living  by  families  of  employed  wage  earners 
and  clerical  workers  in  various  incorne  groups.  Among  the  products 
purchased,  of  course,  were  electric  refrigerators,  washing  machines, 
vacuum  cleaners,  and  electric  stoves  and  hot  plates.  The  results  of 
this  inquiry  are  presented  for  families  at  three  economic  levels — 
representing  family  incomes  of  approximately  $1,000,  $1,600,  and 
$2,100 — in  the  following  summary  and  in  table  24. 

The  figures  represent  average  expenditures  per  family  and  accord- 
ingly are  small,  since  only  a  fraction  of  the  families  make  such  pur- 
chases (or  payments  on  such  purchases)  in  any  one  year.  For  example, 
at  the  $1,000  level,  only  1.1  percent  of  the  families  purchased  electric 
refrigerators  during  the  year,  while  at  the  $2,100  level  12.1  percent  of 
the  families  purchased  such  equipment. 

Table  13. — Average  expenditures  hy  families  of  employed  wage  earners  and  cle;;rical 

workers,  by  economic  level 

[Refer  to  table  24] 


Item 


Refrigerators.. 

Washing  machines 

Vacuum  cleaners 

Ranges  and  hot  plates 


$1,000  income 


Percent- 
age of 
families 
purchas- 
ing 


1.1 
3.4 
0 
0 


Average 
expendi- 
ture per 
family  ' 


2.43 

0 

0 


$1,600  income 


Percent- 
age of 
families 
purchas- 
ing 


6.9 

6.0 

6.0 

.6 


Average 
expendi- 
ture per 
family  ' 


$2,100  income 


Percent- 
ape  of 
families 
purchas- 
ing 


$11.34 
3.81 
2.C3 
.40 


12.1 
5.8 

10.fi 
2.2 


Average 
expendi- 
ture per 
family  ' 


$21.57 
3.93 
5,19 
2.0O 


'  Average  for  families  in  42  large  cities  from  unpublished  data  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  based  on 
total  tiumber  of  families  in  groups,  not  on  families  purchasing. 

As  was  to  be  anticipated,  the  upper  economic  level  spent  consider- 
ably more  for  electric  refrigerators  than  did  the  middle  group;  the 
latter  in  turn  spent  very  much  more  than  did  the  lowest  economic  level. 
A  similar  sharp  contrast  in  expenditures  appears  for  vacuum  cleaners 
and  electric  stoves;  for  washing  machines,  as  might  be  inferred  from 
its  saturation  pattern,  the  difference  is  less  striking. 

Families  in  the  $1,000  level  spent  an  average  of  only  $1.98  for  elec- 
tric refrigerators,  $2.43  for  washing  machines  and  no  expenditures 
were  recorded  for  vacuum  cleaners  and  electric  stoves.  It  is  apparent 
that  these  families  did  not  participate  significantly  in  the  markets  for 
those  products.  Consequently  the  bulk  of  sales  was  to  families  in  the 
upper  and  middle  income  classes. 

Income  residuals. — The  reasons  for  this  greater-than-proportionate 
reduction  in  expenditures  for  electrical  household  equipment  as 
income  falls  are  apparent.  A  family  can  afford  to  purchase  an  ex- 
pensive piece  of  equipment  such  as  an  electric  refrigerator  only  if  it 
has  already  met,  or  made  provision  to  meet,  the  expenses  incurred  for 
what  are  commonly  spoken  of  as  the  "necessities  of  life" — food, 
clothing,  shelter,  and  personal  care.  Consequently,  the  amount  of  its 
income  which  a  family  may  be  able  to  spend  for  household  equipment 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  131 

should  be  measured  only  after  the  family's  expenditures  on  th^se 
items  are  deducted. 

In  chart  XXI  the  income  which  remains  after  deductions  are  made 
for  these  primary  expenditures  is  shown  as  a  percentage  of  total 
income. 

In  general,  it  is  apparent  that  nonrelief  *  families  in  the  very  low 
income  brackets  actually  expend  more  than  their  total  incomes, 
whereas  those  in  the  upper  brackets  have  a  residual  of  more  than 
40  percent.  It  is  out  of  this  residual  that  purchases  of  such  equipment 
must  come,  as  well  as  expenditures  for  such  items  as  transportation, 
personal  care,  medical  care,  recreation,  tobacco,  drugs  and  cosmetics 
and  taxes.  The  opportunities  of  purchasing  such  products  as  refriger- 
ators, vacuum  cleaners,  or  washing  machines  arc  correspondingly 
limited. 

This  docs  not  mean  that  the  lower  income  groups  must  be  dropped 
from  consideration  as  a  potential  market  for  these  goods.  However, 
the  extent  of  that  market  should  be  measured  not  in  terms  of  the 
entire  income  of  a  family,  but  rather  in  terms  of  that  share  of  the  total 
income  which  remains  after  more  urgent  expenditures  have  been  made. 
Obviously,  if  these  markets  are  to  be  tapped,  prices  must  be  low  and 
payments  must  be  extended  over  substantial  periods  of  time. 

COMPETITION   AND  SALES  STRATEGY 

The  expansion  of  certain  household-equipment  industries  since  1920 
has  been  very  marked.  Sales  of  refrigerators,  vacuum  cleaners,  and 
ranges  more  than  trebled,  and  sales  of  washing  machines  and  radios 
more  than  doubled  during  the  period  1932-37.  In  each  industry,  the 
1936-37  peak  was  far  in  excess  of  pxe-depression  levels. 

The  virgin  markets  available  to  these  new  industries  were,  of  course, 
a  primary,  basic  factor  in  their  rapid  development.  Sales  were  stimu- 
lated by  (1)  price  reductions,  (2)  improved  equipment,  quality  and 
appearance,  (3)  modern  merchandising  methods,  and  (4)  general 
business  recovery. 

Price  uniformity. — During  the  downswing  of  the  cycle  from  1929  to 
1932,  the  focus  of  sales  effort  seems  to  have  been  on  prices.  The 
reduction  in  average  unit  retail  value  for  all  these  products  during 
this  period  has  been  described.  (See  p.  112.)  Price  competition 
seems  to  have  been  particularly  active  during  the  most  acute  phase  of 
the  depression.  The  refrigerator  industry  experienced  a  severe  price 
war  during  1931-32;  dunng  its  course  some  boxes  were  sold  slightly 
under  $100  retail. 

From  1932  on,  less  attention  was  given  to  price  and  more  stress 
was  placed  upon  the  development  of  efficient,  modern-styled  equip- 
ment. Prices  were  fairly  uniform  and,  in  general,  price  competition 
was  not  emphasized. 

This  type  of  situation  became  increasingly  characteristic  of  the 
industries  as  the  years  passed.  By  1938  prices  quoted  by  the  leading 
electric-refrigerator  manufacturers,  with  one  important  exception,  had 
approached  a  degree  of  almost  complete  uniformity,  as  is  shown  in 
table  21.  Altogether,  the  concerns  listed  in  the  table  control  at  least 
80  percent  of  the  total  sales  of  electric  refrigerators.     The  one  im- 

*  Many  of  the  families  in  metropolitan  areas  and  large  cities  with  annual  incomes  under  $500  which  main- 
tained tb'-'nselvcs  without  relief  were  those  with  resouroes  to  draw  on  either  in  the  form  of  past  savings  or 
credit. 


132 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chabt  XXI 


INCOME  RESIDUALS  AFTER  PRIMARY  EXPENDITURES 

BY  INCOME  GROUPS 

1935-36 

NON-RELIEF  FAMILIES   INCLUDING   HUSBAND 
AND  WIFE  BOTH  NATIVE   BORN 


NEW   ENGLAND 


250   500   750  1000  1250  1500  1750  2000  2250  2500  3000  3500  4000  5000  7500  10,000 

AND      ANO      AND      AND      AND     AHO     AND      AND      AND      AND      AND      AND      AND      AND     AND      <nd 
UNDER  UNDER   UNDER   UNDER   UNDER   UNDER  UNDER   UNDER*  UNDER   UHDER   UNDER   UNDER   UNDER   UNDER   UNDER 

500      750     1000    1250      1500    1750    2000    2250    2500   3000    3500   4000   5000    7500   10,000  OVER 
INCOME   CROUPS  IN  DOLLARS 
—  METROPOLIS  ECTtjBsa   MIDDLE-SIZED  CITIES 

QZZB  LARGE  CITY  iyA>//A   SMALL  CITIES 

U.  S  BUREAU  OF  LABOR  STATISTICS;  STUDY   OF  CONSUMER  PURCHASES,  URBAN   SERIES 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  XXI — Continued 


133 


INCOME  RESIDUALS  AFTER  PRIMARY  EXPENDITURES 

BY  INCOME  GROUPS 

1935-36 

NON-RELIEF   FAMILIES   INCLUDING   HUSBAND 
AND  WIFE  BOTH  NATIVE   BORN 


SOUTHEAST 


250      500      750     1000     1250    1500    1750    2000   2250    2500  3000    3500  4000   5000   7500   10,000 

AND  AND  AND  AND  AHO  AHU  AND  AND  AND  AND  AND  AND  AND  AND  AND  .„- 

UNDCN      UNOCfl      UNDER     UNDER       UNDER      UNDER      UNDER       UNDER      UNDER      UNDER      UNDER       UNDER     UNDER      UNDER     UNDER         *"'' 

500      750     1000     1250     1500    1750    2000   2250    2500  3000    3500  4000   5000  7500  10,000  OVER 
INCOME  GROUPS  IN  DOLLARS 


I  LARGE   CITY  ^253 -MIDDLE-SIZED  CITIES 

U.  S  BUREAU   OF  LABOR   STATISTICS;   STUDY   OF   CONSUMER   PURCHASES,  URBAN    SERIES  


234  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

portant  deviation  from  the  pattern  of  price  uniformity  is  the  Coldspot 
refrigerator,  handled  through  a  mass  distributor. 

The  uniformity  of  prices  among  the  various  companies  during  1938 
is  quite  apparent  from  above  table.  In  addition  to  this  uniformity  of 
Ust  prices,  guarantees  were  generally  uniform,  consisting  in  most  cases 
of  a  one-year  guarantee  on  cabinet  shelves,  traj^s,  and  accessories,  a  one- 
year  guarantee  on  controls,  and-  a  5-year  "replacement"  or  "protec- 
tion" plan  on  the  refrigerator  system  itself.  In  the  cast  of  all  the 
companies  listed,  except  Stewart-Warner,  these  guarantee  features 
are  included  in  the  list  price;  if  the  price  quotation  for  this  company 
is  corrected  by  adding  the  charge  for  the  guarantee,  the  price  uni- 
formity becomes  even  more  striking.^"  During  1939  this  price 
uniformity  continued;  the  important  change  which  occurred  early 
in  1940  will  be  discussed  subsequently. 

Prices  in  the  washing-machine  and  vacuum-cleaner  industries  are 
also  uniform.  In  both  of  these  industries  the  influence  of  "price 
lines"  is  predominant.  Most  vacuum  cleaners  and  washing  machines 
sell  at  either  $29.95,  $39.95,  $49.95,  or  $59.95.  In  the  case  of  washing 
machines  the  size  of  the  machine  offered  at  each  price  line  is  much  the 
same  for  each  of  the  major  companies.  Thus,  competition  is  removed 
from  the  sphere  of  price  and  size  of  machine  to  the  efficiency  of  opera- 
tion and  to  general  quality  appeal. 

Concentration. — It  is  probable  that  the  trend  toward  price  uni- 
formity in  the  refrigerator  industry  in  the  years  following  1933  was 
facilitated  by  increasing  concentration  among  producers.  Business 
mortality  was  high  during  the  depression.  Thus  the  Electric  Re- 
frigerator News  in  May  1933,  published  a  list  of  concerns  which  had 
ceased  manufacturing  electric  refrigerators.  The  250  producers  in 
1932  had  been  reduced  to  75;  110  had  gone  out  of  business,  41  could 
not  be  reached  by  mail,  and  24  had  been  absorbed  by  other 
manufacturers. 

This  high  mortality  undoubtedly  reflected  the  stress  of  the  de- 
pression generally,  ani,  more  particularly,  the  severe  price  war  of 
1931-32."  ■  In  addition,  however,  a  sharp  reduction  in  the  number  of 
concerns  is  often  a  symptom  of  an  industry's  approaching  maturity 
and  represents  a  more  or  less  inevitable  "weeding  out"  process 
following  its  developmental  stage. 

Table  22  reveals  the  degree  of  concentration  among  producers  in 
three  of  these  appliance  industries  during  1937.  The  output  of  the 
four  largest  producers  in  each  case  is  expressed  as  a  percentage  of 
total  output  in  the  industry.  Concentration  was  least  marked  in  the 
washing-machine  industry  where  four  producers  accounted  for  more 
than  half  of  the  total  production;  it  was  greatest  in  the  electric- 
refrigerator  industry  where  four  concerns  produced  approximately 
three-fourths  of  the  total  dollar  value. 

In  appraising  the  significance  of  this  concentration,  certain  relation- 
ships existing  between  companies  should  not  be  neglected.  For 
example,  the  Kelvinator  Co.  manufactures  and  distributes  the 
Leonard  refrigerator,  and,  in  addition,  has  a  substantial  interest  in 
the  Universal   Cooler   Co.'^     Patents   are   of   strategic   importance, 

'»  The  addition  of  a  .$5  "Ruaranteo"  to  the  ILst  price  of  the  Stewart- Warner  6.0-6.9-foot  model  brings  the 
net  price  to  $184.75  which  is  exactly  the  same  price  charged  by  Frigidaire  and  General  Electric. 
«i  Sec  p.  112  above. 
II  Standard  Corporation  Records,  the  Kelvinator-Nash  Corpwration. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         J  35 

especially  in  the  washing-machine  industry.  The  Maytag  Co.,  which 
produces  washing  machines  and  ironing  machines  exclusively,  owns 
the  basic  patents  on  the  type  of  mechanical  agitation  utilized  by  most 
washing-machine  manufacturers.*'  In  the  spring  of  1939,  however, 
the  patent  control  of  the  Maytag  Co.  was  materially  lessened  as  a 
result  of  a  decision  by  the  United  States  Supreme  Court.**  In  the 
electric- refrigerator  industry  the  more  important  patented  features 
are  freely  utilized  by  most  of  the  industry's  members. 

Emphasis  upon  quality. — The  corporations  surviving  the  depres- 
sion— especially  the  large  firms — invested  heavily  in  research  and 
experimeptal  activities.  Modem  sealed  units  for  the  refrigerator 
were  introduced  by  the  majority  of  manufacturers;  "streamlined" 
refrigerator  cabinets  were  perfected;  economic  methods  of  insulation 
were  devised;  and  great  advances  were  made  in  improving  the  internal 
features  of  the  refrigerator.  Washing  machines  acquired  many  new 
features.  The  "spinner"  type  of  machine  was  introduced.  Table- 
top  ranges  with  high-speed  cooking  units  were  developed.  Through- 
out these  industries  important  technological  advances  were  achieved. 
New  designs  and  new  styles  enhanced  not  only  the  appearance  but 
also  the  utility  of  the  appliances. 

At  the  same  time,  sales  effort  was  intensified,  not  only  by  manu-^ 
facturers  and  dealers,  but  also  by  public  utilities  which  sought  to 
expand  the  demand  for  electric  current.  House-to-house  canvassing 
and  demonstrations  of  the  various  products  became  a  common  prac- 
tice. Complete  electrical  kitchens  were  advertised  and  salesmen  were 
trained  to  sell  not  merely  a  single  item,  but  completely  equipped 
kitchens  for  the  home.  Price  was  not  emphasized  duiing  this  period; 
the  focus  of  competition  had  altered.  Advertisements  stressed 
improved  quality,  style,  design,  efficiency,  and  reputation. 

Manufacturers  sought  for  and  developed  new  markets.  This 
required  new  distributors  and  more  outlets.  This  movement  toward 
the  extension  and  expansion  of  distributive  outlets  was  aided  by 
established  retail  stores  of  various  kinds.  Furniture  stores,  hardware 
stores,  music  stores,  automobile  accessories  shops,  and  department 
stores  seized  the  opportunity  to  handle  these  new  and  profitable  lines. 
Today  the  largest  group  of  outlets  is  electrical  specialty  stores  (includ- 
ing radio  stores),  with  department  stores  second,  public  utilities  third, 
and  furniture  stores  fourth. 

Distribution  systems  vary  according  to  product.  In  general,  sales 
are  through  some  sort  of  retail  store,  but  some  of  the  larger  manu- 
facturers of  vacuum  cleaners  maintain  large  sales  staffs  which  conduct 
house-to-house  canvasses  and  sell  by  means  of  demonstration.     This 

'3  Standard  Corporation  Records,  the  Maytag  Corporation.  The  National  Recovery  Administration 
Code  History  of  the  washing-machine  industry  describes  it  as  being  of  a  "very  compact  nature"  and  that 
the  industry  was  "not  troublesome  from  the  viewpoint  of  compHance.  The  small  number  of  violations 
reported  (wore  due  to)  the  fact  that  this  was  a  well-disciplined  industry  *  *  *  "  It  is  possible  that 
patent  arrangements  played  a  role  in  this  experience. 

'<  The  Maytag  Co.  filed  suit  against  several  corporations  for  infringements  of  its  patents.  The  patent, 
Isyjed  July  12, 1932,  to  the  Maytag  Co.,  assignee,  contained  39  claims,  36  of  which  were  for  washing  machines 
and  3  (Kq^-.  1,  38,  and  39)  for  a  method  of  washing  fabrics.  The  Maytag  Co.  contended  that  the  functions 
performed  under  claims  38  and  39  were  distinct  and  separate.  The  Court  decided  otherwise.  To  quote 
the  opinion  delivered  by  Justice  Roberts: 

"The  company  insists  that  the  crucial  difference  lies  in  the  fact  that  in  38  the  moving  fluid  in  the  tub  Is 
said  substantially  to  suspend  the  fabrics,  whereas  in  39  tbe  same  agency  is  said  to  cause  the  fabrics  to  be  freely 
moved  about.  But  the  difference  in  verbiage  describes  no  difference  in  operation  or  result.  We  conclude 
that,  when  read  in  their  entirety,  they  describe  the  same  method  *  *  •  we  are  of  the  opinion  that  the 
patent  is  void  for  failure  to  disclaim  claim  39."  (Afaytag  versus  Hurley  ^Machine  Company,  Easy  Washing 
Washing  Machine  Corporation,  and  General  Electric  Corporation,  59  Supreme  Court  Reporter,  October  term 
1938,  p.  857.) 


136 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


procedure  seems  to  entail  higher  distribution  costs  and  prices  than  the 
orthodox  retail  channel  used  by  another  major  group  of  manu- 
facturers.'* 

Prior  to  1931,  most  manufacturers  presented  relatively  few  models 
and  styles  of  each  item  of  equipment.  After  business  recovery  began 
in  the  spring  of  1933,  the  number  of  price  lines  was  increased,  affording 
the  consumer  a  wider  variety  of  choice.  Instead  of  showing  only 
three  or  four  refrigerators  as  was  the  case  in  1929,  by  1935  the  average 
dealer  was  able  to  present  to  the  prospective  customer  8  or  10  distinct 
lines.  In  general,  at  least  until  1940,  there  has  been  some  tendency 
to  reduce  the  spreads  between  prices  of  different  models.'^ 

After  1932,  when  efforts  to  expand  the  market  were  intensified, 
attempts  were  made  to  introduce  models  wliich  would  appeal  to 
families  in  the  lower-income  groups.  For  a  time  efforts  were  made  to 
sell  small  4-foot  refrigerators,  which  were  the  lowest-price  models,  to 
those  homes  wliich  could  not  afford  to  buy  the  larger,  more  costly 
equipment.  During  the  early  stages  of  the  recovery,  sales  of  4-foot 
and  smaller  boxes  predominated.  During  1934  and  1935,  however, 
advertising  and  sales  effort  were  directed  primarily  toward  marketing 
5-foot,  6-foot,  and  7-foot  boxes  which  are  more  useful  for  the  typical 
household.  Prices  were  further  reduced  on  these  lines,  in  order  to 
widen  their  appeal.  This  trend  has  continued,  and  at  present  the 
6-foot  box  is  the  most  popular  size. 


Year 

Percentage  distribution  of  sales  by  size  of  box 

4  cubic  feet 

6  cubic  feet 

6  cubic  feet 

7  cubic  feet 

1934  .             .      ... 

31 
13 

21 
25 

13 
35 

11 

1937 

9 

In  other  items  of  equipment — washing  machines,  ranges,  cleaners — 
salesmen  constantly  warn  against  purchase  of  small,  low-quality  mod- 
els. They  have  been  educated  to  "sell  quality"  and  to  sell  those 
models,  particularly  the  higher-priced  lines,  which  bring  them  larger 
commissions. 

"Leader"  selling  has  come  to  be  a  standard  practice  in  these  indus- 
tries. For  example,  most  manufacturers  of  refrigerators  produce  at 
least  one  model  stripped  of  all  the  gadgets  and  extra  features  which 
are  included  in  the  "deluxe"  styles.  These  models  are  advertised  to 
gain  the  attention  of  bargain  seekers.  The  "leader"  models  usually 
lack  merely  the  eye-catching  innovations,  the  special  trays,  the  evap- 
orators, and  specialties  of  the  higher-priced  lines.  They  are  available 
at  relatively  low  prices  and  have  come  to  represent  a  fairly  large  pro- 
portion of  sales.  On  the  other  hand,  prospective  buyers  attracted  by 
the  advertisement  are  often  persuaded  by  the  dealer  to  buy  a  higher- 
priced  line  instead.  Similarly,  in  washing  machines,  radios,  and 
cleaners,  models  stripped  of  gadgets  and  attachments  are  made  avail- 
able at  relatively  low  prices  to  meet  the  demand  of  the  "price  con- 
scious" segment  of  the  market. 

:» See  p.  146. 

"  In  the  case  of  washing  machines,  the  various  lines  offered  are  usually  priced  et  $10  intervals,  at  5  cents 
under  the  even  figure.  (E.  g.,  $29.9S,  $39.95,  $49.95,  etc.)  Some  manufacturers  claim  that  this  pricing  tech- 
nique results  In  the  sale  of  more  higher-priced  models. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER.         137 

The  turning  'point — the  1937-38  recession. — Sales  had  advanced  at  a 
rapid  pace  throughout  the  recovery  period  from  1932  to  1937;  the 
latter  year  was  the  all-time  peak  in  sales  for  all  of  these  products." 
Production  far  exceeded  that  of  1929. 

The  first  and  second  quarters  of  1937  represented  prosperous  levels 
of  business.  Aided  by  modem  merchandising  policies,  advertising, 
favorable  terms  and  conditions  of  sale,  new  styles,  efficiency  of  equip- 
ment, and  general  business  recovery,  sales  came  easily. 

The  subsequent  experience  of  the  refrigerator  industry  may  be  con- 
sidered typical  of  the  group.  Manufacturers  had  expanded  plant  and 
equipment  facilities  throughout  the  period  1932  to  1937.  As  a  result 
they  were  prepared  to  meet  the'  high  levels  of  demand  which  came 
during  the  early  months  of  the  latter  year.  However,  encouraged  by 
the  large  increase  in  sales  during  the  first  quarter  of  1937  and  by 
favorable  reports  from  distributors  in  all  parts  of  the  country,  they 
continued  to  expand  plants  to  meet  still  further  anticipated  increases 
in  sales.  Manufacturing  activity  was  maintained  at  a  high  rate 
throughout  the  summer  of  1937,  despite  accmnulating  evidence  of  an 
impending  business  set-back.  Heavy  inventories  were  created  during 
this  period ;  production  was  not  curtailed  for  some  time  after  the  rate 
of  purchase  had  fallen  off. 

Plans  were  being  made  to  modify  the  seasonal  pattern  of  the  indus- 
try. Showings  of  new  models,  which  were  usually  held  after  the  turn 
of  the  year,  were  scheduled  for  a  pre-Christmas  date  during  1937. 
The  industry  had  planned  to  stimulate  winter  sales  by  promoting  holi- 
day gift  buying  and  elaborate  preparations  had  been  made  accordingly. 
The  change  may  have  been  suggested  by  the  successful  experience  of 
the  automobile  industry  which  had  altered  its  seasonal  pattern  in  1935 
by  changing  the  date  of  introduction  of  new  models. 

It  became  evident  early  in  the  summer  of  1937  that  the  decline  in 
sales  would  be  much  greater  than  normal  seasonal  expectation.  Buy- 
ing dropped  off  rapidly  during  the  summer  and  fall.  The  expected 
increase  in  sales  at  the  end  of  the  year  during  the  Christmas  holidays 
did  not  materialize.  The  downward  trend  became  even  more  severe 
during  the  early  months  of  1938.  During  the  latter  year,  refrigerator 
sales  were  46  percent  below  the  1937  peak  level. 

Inventories  rose  rapidly.  At  the  end  of  1937  there  were  300,000 
refrigerators  in  dealers'  hands  as  compared  with  only  125,000  during 
December  1936. 

The  curtailment  of  public  purchasing  power  was  reflected  in  the 
failure  of  many  conditional  buyers  to  keep  up  th  nr  monthly  pajrments. 
Repossessions  of  equipment  which  had  been  sold  on  time  increased 
sharply  during  the  winter  of  1937-38.  Some  manufacturers  have  indi- 
cated their  opinion  that  the  favorable  credit  terms  which  had  been 
offered  prior  to  the  break  were  at  least  partly  responsible  for  this  high 
rate  of  return.  Presumably  the  impact  of  the  recession  hit  with  espe- 
cial force  marginal  buyers  in  the  lower-income  levels  whose  purchases 
had  been  made  possible  in  the  first  instance  by  the  easy  terms  offered. 

The  large  credit  companies  seem  to  have  become  aware  of  this  situa- 
tion somewhat  belatedly.  Their  policy  was  changed  during  1937,  and 
credit  facilities  were  generally  restricted,  terms  of  payment  shortened, 

"  In  the  case  of  washing  machines,  although  dollar  volume  reached  its  peak  in  1937,  the  number  of  units 
Bold  was  greater!  n  1936. 


J  38  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

larger  down  payments  required,  and  the  paying  ability  of  prospective 
purchasers  more  carefully  examined.  These  changes  may  have  con- 
tributed to  the  contraction  in  sales.  During  1939,  however,  there  was 
evidence  that  the  terms  of  conditional  sales  were  again  being  made 
more  liberal.  Such  liberalization  is  apparently  characteristic  of  periods 
of  active  demand.    Terms  are  usually  tightened  up  when  sales  decline. 

PROBLEMS  OF  SALES  POLICY  DETERMINATION 

It  is  evident  that  some  at  least  of  the  industries  considered  in  the 
foregoing  section,  particularly  the  refrigerator,  washing  machine,  and 
vacuum  cleaner  industries,  have  come  to  critical  turning  points  due  to 
the  increasing  saturation  of  a  substantial  portion  of  their  original 
markets,  particularly  in  the  more  prosperous  sector  of  the  population. 
The  effect  of  this  change  in  market  conditions  was  forcibly  revealed  in 
the  sharp  dechnes  in  sales  experienced  by  these  industries  during  the 
1937-38  recession.  During  1939  there  seemed  abundant  evidence 
that  their  initial  period  of  rapid  technological  development,  aggressive 
price  reductions,  and  vigorous  growth  had  apparently  reached  or  was 
rapidly  approaching  an  end. 

It  is  clear  that  this  change  in  market  conditions  reflecting  ap- 
proaching maturitjr  must  be  met  by  corresponding  changes  in  market- 
mg  techniques  and  in  price  policies  if  the  expansion  possibilities  of  these 
industries  are  to  be  fully  realized.  The  policies  which  these  industries 
followed  between  1932-37  seem  to  have  been  well  suited  to  the  ex- 
ploitation of  the  original  market  among  families  of  the  middle  and 
upper  income  brackets.  This  market  is,  however,  rapidly  declining 
as  evidenced  by  the  saturation  figures  which  have  been  presented. 
Consequently,  the  bulk  of  future  sales  must  be  either  to  famihes  in 
income  brackets  who  have  not  hitherto  been  able  to  afford  the  pur- 
chase of  these  kinds  of  equipment,  or  else  they  must  be  sales  for  the 
purpose  of  replacing  worn  out  or  obsolescent  equipment.  Maximum 
expansion  would  be  achieved  through  appeal  to  both  of  these  markets 
concurrently. 

It  is  convenient  to  consider  these  two  possibihties  separately. 
Consequently,  the  discussion  will  first  proceed  to  an  examination  of 
possibilities  of  expanding  the  original  market,  particularly  among 
members  of  the  lower  income  groups.  The  possibilities  of  stimulating 
replacement  sales  will  be  examined  subsequently. 

EXPANDING  THE  ORIGINAL  SALES  MARKET 

Quality  emphasis  and  advertising. — Since  approximately  1932,  and 
until  1940,  programs  for  expanding  sales  in  these  industries  (as  well  as 
competition  between  rival  firms  for  their  shares  of  the  market)  have 
focused  primarily  upon  nonprice  techniques.  Prices  throughout  this 
period  for  all  these  industries  and  for  most  of  the  firms  within  each  in- 
dustry, with  the  large  mail-order  houses  constituting  a  notable  ex- 
ception, remained  stable.  Sales  effort  concentrated  partly  upon 
advertising  and  sales  campaigns  designed  to  acquaint  the  public  with 
the  virtues  of  the  respective  apphances,  and  partly  upon  improvements 
of  quality  and  appearance.  Guarantees  were  ejxtended  to  assure 
the  consumer  of  the  reliability  and  durability  of  the  product.     Im- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         139 

provements  in  efficiency  of  operation  were  continually  sought  through 
constant  laboratory  analysis  and  research.^* 

In  the  absence  of  revolutionary  changes  in  mechanical  details  and 
construction,  the  future  effectiveness  of  these  techniques  seems  clearly 
limited.  Although  advertising  wiU  probably  remain  an  important 
instrument  of  rivalry  between  competing  concerns,  its  value  in  ex- 
panding the  market  is  conditioned  by  the  dwindling  number  of 
potential  original  purchasers.  Moreover,  there  is  some  evidence 
that  the  ingenuity  of  advertising  copywriters  is  beginning  to  be 
strained  in  devising  new  forms  of  appeal.  Every  conceivable  aspect 
of  an  electric  refrigerator,  for  example,  has  been  exploited  in  advertis- 
ing. Such  features  as  the  size  and  shape  of  the  box,  "streamlining,'* 
the  "efficient"  compression  unit,  the  number  of  trays,  the  control 
over  temperature,  etc.,  have  been  described  repeatedly  in  advertising 
copy.^^  The  exhaustion,  of  "sharp  angles,"  the  similarity  of  advertis- 
ing of  the  various  producers,  and  the  consequent  necessity  of  repeti- 
tion lead  to  extremes  in  advertising  which  often  mitigate  its  effect- 
iveness. ^'^ 

The  washing  machine  industry  has  not  been  characterized  by 
advertising  as  extensive  as  has  the  electrical  refrigerator  industry. 
Instead,  it  relies  heavily  upon  a  system  of  direct  sales  solicitation. 
Manufacturers  often  maintain  elaborate  schemes  for  establishing 
prospect  lists  and  for  guiding  "follow-up"  work.^^ 

18  The  early  electric  refrigerators  were  affected  by  constant  (liflBcalties  with  motors,  compressors,  mechan- 
ical drives,  cooling  units,  stuffing  boxes,  freezing  trays,  and  enamel  finish.  Cork  Insulation  was  expensive 
and  was  only  moderately  successful  in  excluding  heat.  As  a  result  of  research,  however,  all  of  these  diffi- 
culties were  overcome.  Enamels  were  developed  which  enabled  the  entire  cabinet  to  be  fabricated  and 
fired  as  one  piece.  New  and  superior  types  of  insulation  such  as  wood  fibre,  rock  wool,  aluminum  foil,  glass 
wool  and  paper  were  devised.  In  addition  a  noncorrosive,  nontoxic,  noninflammable,  nonexplosive  and 
Inexpensive  refrigerant  was  created,  dichloro-difluoro-methane  or  "freon."  This  refrigerant — which  boils  at 
21  degrees  below  zero — was  immeasurably  superior  to  SOi,  ammonia,  and  methyl  chloride.  This  improve- 
ment has  alone  contributed  materially  to  the  growth  of  consumer  acceptance  of  the  electric  refrigerator 
(H.  A.  Toulmin,  Jr.,  Patents  and  the  Public  Interest,  Harper  and  Bros.,  1939,  pp.  149,  150.) 

i»  In  the  words  of  Printers'  Ink  Monthly,  August  1937: 

"The  selling  of  refrigerators  requires  the  massing  of  all  conceivable  sales  influences.  It  becomes  evident 
to  one  who  compares  the  methods  of  the  leading  companies  that  mere  sharp  angles  will  not  sell  refrigerators 
any  more.  As  an  industry  matures,  angles  disappear  and  products  approach  uniformity.  Advertising  at 
the  same  time  takes  on  a  similarity. 

"Probably  nothing  is  so  striking  about  refrigerator  advertising  as  its  similarity.  Probably  no  one  feels 
this  more  keenly  than  the  advertisers  themselves.  Assuming  that  Joe  Doakes,  the  common  man,  has  an 
analytical  mind,  he  doubtless  compares  the  advertising  of  the  leading  makes  with  growing  confusion.  It 
is  certainly  impossible  for  him  to  decide  from  the  advertising  which  of  them  is  best  for  his  purposes." 

>ii  A  few  examples  of  these  extremes  are  as  follows: 

"New  super-duty  Frigidaire  with  the  meter-miser  cuts  current  cost  amazingly!  Proves  completeness 
never  before  known  in  all  five  basic  services  for  home  refrigeration." 

"The  new  Kelvinator  is  plus-powered.  It  has  as  much  as  double  the  cooling  capacity  of  other  well- 
known  refrigerators  of  equal  .''ize.  The  new  Kelvinator  runs  only  half  as  many  minutes  per  day — during 
the  rest  of  the  time  it  maintains  low  temperatures  using  no  current  at  all." 

Incidentally,  this  latter  type  of  extreme  advertising  resulted  in  action  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commis- 
sion.   (Federal  Trade  Commission,  Stipulation  No.  1749,  and  Docket  No.  3125.) 

An  indication  that  the  advertising  features  of  the  product  have  been  exhausted  is  revealed  in  the  ten- 
dency of  the  General  Electric  Co.,  to  become  philosophical  in  its  advertising: 

"Life    *    •    ♦"  General  Electric  remarks,  "a  few  fleeting  measures  of  conscious  time    •    •    •    precious 

•  *    •    packed  with  infinite  possibilities— but  how  to  make  the  most  of  our  time?    It  flows  away  so  fast 

•  •    *    priceless,  because  nothing  can  purchase  more  time  than  is  given  to  us  all    *    •    *" 

"  The  Maytag  Co.,  for  example,  goes  to  great  lengths  in  suggesting  methods  for  obtaining  narnes  of  pros- 
pects. These  consist  of:  Contacting  regular  customers  who  come  into  the  store;  personal  solicitation  of 
Maytag  owners;  field  solicitation;  circular  letter  with  return  card;  newspaper  advertising;  exhibits  at  auto 
shows,  fairs,  carnivals,  and  public  gatherings;  cooking  schools  and  home  sliows;  demonstrations  at  church 
and  society  activities,  clubs,  etc.;  guessing  contests;  drawing  and  registration  schemes;  bonus  offered  to 
Maytag  owners  who  turn  in  prospects  that  result  in  sales;  rough  survey,  the  salesmen  call  at  every  fifth 
house;  demonstrating  to  high-school  domestic-science  class;  advertising  second-hand  washers  in  classified 
ads,  some  of  those  answering  can  be  traded  up;  store  and  widow  demonstrations;  newspaper  coupons,  the 
company  recommends  some  such  offer  as  "This  week's  washing  done  free;"  contacting  newlyweds;  follow 
birth  announcements;  locate  washerwoman  prospects  by  following  up  "washing  taken  in"  ads  in  news- 
papers; watch  "help  wanted"  and  "situation"  or  "laundress  wanted"  ads  in  newspapers;  newly  wired 
homes;  swapping  prospects;  regular  charge-account  customers;  bookkeepers,  repairmen,  linemen,  clerks, 
etc.;  Maytag  on  truck  at  customer's  door;  getting  husband's  permission  first  to  bring  the  machine  to  tie 
home;  newspaper  news,  leads;  gas  inspectors,  meter  readers,  etc.;  special  invitation  cards  to  the  store. 
(Printers'  Ink  Monthly,  August  1937.) 


l^Q  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

In  tlie  vacuum-cleaner  industry,  as  has  been  noted,  two  principal 
producers  maintain  their  own  salesmen  and  rely  upon  house-to-house 
canvassing.  This  necessitates  the  establishment  and  maintenance  by 
the  manufacturer  of  branch  warehouses,  district  sales  managers, 
branch  managers,  crew  managers,  and  canvassers.  In  addition,  con- 
siderable amounts  are  spent  in  the  education  of  salesmen  and  in  devis- 
ing effective  sales  techniques.  Companies  selling  through  ordinary 
retail  channels  apparently  find  it  more  difficult  to  achieve  high  sales 
volume.  It  is  the  opinion  of  many  in  the  industry  that  house-to- 
house  canvassing  is  necessary  in  order  to  persuade  the  housewife  that 
she  is  eliminating  only  part  of  the  dirt  from  her  home  with  her  carpet 
sweeper  or  her  old  cleaner. 

In  each  of  these  cases  the  sales  techniques  which  have  been  described 
are  somewhat  expensive.  Yet  it  seems  unlikely  that  they  will  be 
materially  modified  in  any  particular  in  the  near  future.  Although 
their  value  in  increasing  the  total  sales  volume  of  the  respective 
industries  may  be  limited,  particularly  in  view  of  the  present  degree 
of  saturation,  they  nevertheless  constitute  effective  competitive  tech- 
niques. Consequently,  no  one  company  can  abandon  them  without 
risking  some  loss  of  its  share  of  the  industry's  sales  volume.  In  any 
appraisal  of  the  expansion  prospects  for  each  of  these  industries  as  a 
whole,  therefore,  these  particular  aspects  of  nonprice  competition  may 
be  somewhat  detrimental  in  that  they  impose  elements  of  cost  which 
must  in  turn  be  reflected  in  the  price  level. 

Other  forms  of  nonprice  competition  which  these  industries  have 
recently  utilized  may  not  involve  any  material  additions  to  cost. 
Nevertheless,  it  is  doubtful  whether  "streamlining"  of  styles  or  the 
further  extension  of  attractive  guarantees  can  be  counted  upon  to 
expand  markets  appreciably.  In  fact,  as  some  of  these  techniques 
come  to  be  generally  utilized,  they  may  even  lose  their  value  as  com- 
petitive devices.  When,  for  example,  one  or  two  refrigerator  pro- 
ducers first  introduced  long- term  guarantees,  these  guarantees  may 
have  had  some  effect  in  augmenting  the  manufacturers'  respective 
shares  of  the  market.  Soon,  however,  the  practice  of  granting  long- 
term  guarantees  became  general.  At  present  these  are  so  uni- 
form that  they  are  no  longer  a  basis  for  distinguishing  the  product  of 
one  manufacturer  from  that  of  his  rival.  Shortly  after  this  uniformity 
in  guarantees  was  achieved,  an  editorial  in  a  trade  publication  pointed 
out  the  consequences: 

IS   THE   6-yEAR   GUARANTEE   NECESSARY? 

A  recent  trip  into  the  field  reveals  the  fact,  that  electric  dealers  are  highly  dis- 
satisfied with  the  epidemic  of  5-year  guarantees  which  seem  to  have  broken  out 
in  the  national  advertising  of  the  electric  refrigerators.  The  point  is,  of  course, 
that  the  advertisements  are  worded  to  give  the  customer  the  impression  that  the 
merchandise  purchased  is  warranted  against  interruption  of  whatever  character 
over  a  5-year  period,  whereas  that  is  not  intended  at  all.  The  manufacturer  is 
guaranteeing  his  wares  only  against  defects  for  which  he  is  responsible. 

Originally  the  guarantee  found  an  excuse  for  itself  in  that  it  was  the  exclusive 
promise  of  one  company  and  so  formed  a  sales  argument  for  the  salesmen  handling 
that  line.  Now,  when  practically  every  manufacturer  makes  the  same  promise, 
it  does  not  even  offer  a  talking  point  against  rival  makes.^^ 

In  summary  there  seems  good  reason  to  doubt  the  efficacy  of  these 
nonprice  sales  techniques  as  means  of  expanding  the  markets  for 

'*  Electrical  Merchandising,  December  1936,<  p.  22. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         141 

electrical  appliances,  once  saturation  has  reached  a  relatively  high  level 
among  those  who  can  afford  to  purchase  at  the  prevailing  prices. 
However  it  is  possible  that  some  future  revolutionary  change  in  me- 
chanical detail  and  construction  might  improve  the  refrigerator  to 
such  an  extent  that  the  replacement  market  would  be  greatly  stim- 
ulated. 

Credit  terms. — Before  turning  to  the  level  of  prices  as  such,  it  may 
be  well  to  consider  briefly  the  structure  of  credit  terms  on  conditional 
sales.  Thel"e  are  four  basic  elements  to  the  credit  transaction  which 
may  be  examined  as  offering  possibilities  of  stimulating  sales.  These 
are: 

1 .  The  size  of  the  down  payment. 

2.  The  period  over  which  payments  are  to  be  made. 

3.  The  effective  interest  rate. 

4.  The  degree  of  emphasis  upon  the  purchaser's  financial  status. 
During  the  period  of  increased  demand  in  1936  and  1937,  efforts 

were  made  to  liberalize  each  one  of  these  aspects  of  the  credit  trans- 
action. In  part,  at  least,  this  reflected  the  activities  of  various. 
Federal  agencies,  such  as  the  Federal  Housing  Administration-  and 
the  Electric  Farm  aud  Home  Authority,  which  financed  equipment 
sales  at  low  interest  rates.  Similar  practices  were  adopted  by  the 
industry  generally  and  by  private  financing  companies.  Down  pay- 
ments were  gradually  reduced  until,  in  many  cases,  none  at  all  were 
required. 

The  period  for  payment  was  gradually  extended  from  the  earlier 
practice  of  18  to  24  mouths;  first  to  30  months,  and  later  to  as  long  as 
36  months.  Interest  rates  were  cut,  particularly  by  public  utility 
companies  and  by  large  department  stores.  Apparently  too,  pro- 
gressively less  effort  was  made  to  examine  the  prospective  customer's 
financial  position.  It  has  been  mentioned  above  (p.  137)  that  distress 
among  consumers  during  the  1937-38  recession  resulted  in  a  large  num- 
ber of  repossessions,  part  of  which,  at  least,  reflected  the  liberality  with 
which  credit  had  been  extended.  In  an  effort  to  avoid  a  recurrence 
of  this  experience,  some  attempts  were  made  to  tighten  the  credit 
structure.  Apparently,  however,  the  only  important  difference 
between  conditions  today  and  those  preceding  the  recent  recession  is 
a  somewhat  greater  surveillance  of  the  prospective  customer's  financial 
status.  Otherwise,  down  payments  are  still  small  or  not  required, 
interest  rates  low  and  the  period  of  payment  long. 

It  is  true  that  the  decision  of  many  prospective  purchasers  is  often 
governed  more  by  the  size  of  the  required  monthly  payment  than 
by  the  aggregate  amount  which  they  are  called  upon  to_  pay.  If 
monthly  payments  could  be  made  smaller,  sales  might  be  increased. 
On  the  other  hand,  the  interest  rate  charged  by  many  sellers  is  now 
so  moderate  that  further  reductions  would  be  unlikely  to  affect  the 
size  of  the  monthly  payment  appreciably,  and  the  period  oyer  which 
payment  is  extended  is  probably  as  long  as  is  consistent  with  sound 
financial  policy.  Consequently,  further  liberalization  of  credit  terms 
does  not  seem  to  be  a  promising  method  of  stimulating  the  market 
for  these  appliances.     It  is  the  retail  price  which  is  the  basic  element. 

Price  reductions. — The  most  obvious  means  of  stimulating  original 
sales  among  families  in  the  lower  income  brackets  is  a  policy  of  price 
reduction.     Between  1932  and  1939,  however,  the  prices  of  these 


142  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

products  were  maintained  at  relatively  stable  levels  and,  except  for 
refrigerators,  these  levels  still  prevail.  While  this  has  represented 
the  general  policy  there  has  nevertheless  been  some  effort,  particu- 
larly in  the  refrigerator  and  washing  machine  industries,  to  introduce 
so-called  "stripped"  lines. 

Since  1937  most  of  the  major  refrigerator  companies  have  introduced 
special,  low-priced  6-foot  models.  These  models  are  "stripped"  of 
the  many  special  features  and  accessories  found  on  the  regular  models. 
The  trays  do  not  slide  out;  there  are  no  special  devices  for  removing 
the  ice  cubes  from  their  container  and  various  other  similar  features 
are  omitted. 

Only  in  the  6-foot  line — which  retailed  at  about  $175  in  1939 — has 
the  new  model  been  introduced.  During  1938  and  1939  the  reduction 
in  price  by  most  producers  was  approximately  $35,  or  to  about  $140. 
This  price  was  still  beyond  the  range  of  many  potential  purchasers  of 
limited  means,  but  it  did  serve  as  an  attractive  price  line  for  some  of 
the  lower  income  families. 

The  new  line  was  introduced  primarily  as  a  "leader,"  Thus  adver- 
tisements often  proclaimed  that  a  6-foot  box  of  a  well-known  producer 
.was  to  be  offered  for  sale  at  the  "amazingly"  low  price  of  $149.50. 
Customers  who  were  attracted  to  the  store  by  such  an  advertisement 
were  frequently  urged  by  the  salesman  to  purchase  one  of  the  "de  luxe" 
or  "regular"  models  instead  of  the  low-priced  "leader,"  ^^ 

The  "leader"  sales  technique  is  also  utilized  in  the  electrical  washing- 
machine  industry.  In  this  case  the  "leader"  motive,  while  perhaps 
uppermost,  is  accompanied  by  an  even  keener  awareness  of  the  poten- 
tial market  for  such  a  product  among  lower-income  groups.  Thus, 
washing-machine  manufacturers  have  acknowledged  indebtedness  to 
the  stimulation  of  their  sales  resulting  from  relief  payments.  Pre- 
sumably, therefore,  these  cheap  lines  of  washing  machines  have  con- 
tributed materially  to  sales  in  their  own  right,  and  not  merely  in  their 
capacity  as  "leaders." 

Vacuum  cleaner  manufacturers  have  apparently  made  little  effort 
to  introduce  similar  "special"  lines.  Partly  this  may  reflect  the 
nature  of  the  product-  partly  it  may  be  due  to  the  physical  difficulty 
of  selling  more  than  a  single  line  through  the  house-to-house  canvassing 
system.  Where  price  leaders  have  been  utilized  in  this  industry,  old 
cleaners  have  been  reconditioned  to  serve  this  purpose. 

Despite  the  emphasis  on  the  "leader"  aspects  of  these  special  lines, 
they  reflected  a  realization  by  the  manufacturers  of  the  increasing 
role  which  price  consciousness  among  consumers  is  pla,ying  in  the 
market  for  these  electrical  appliances.  To  the  extent  to  which  serious 
effort  was  actually  devoted  to  selling  these  cheaper  lines  to  purchasers 
of  moderate  means,  they  have  resulted  in  some  expansion  of  the  poten- 
tial market.  The  price  difference  was  sufficient  to  attract  certain 
marginal  buyers  that  could  not  afford  the  regular  models.  However, 
this  effect  was  probably  somewhat  narrowed  by  the  practice  of  many 
salesmen  in  treating  these  models  as  substandard,  since  some  con- 

»  In  sales  terminolof;y  this  selling  technique  is  known  as  the  set-back  method.  The  customer,  attracted 
into  the  store  by  the  "leader,"  is  first  shown  the  most  expensive  de-luxe  models.  If  he  indicates  that  the 
price  Is  too  high,  the  salesman  leads  him  to  the  standard  or  regular  models,  which  are  still  at  least  $30  above 
the  price  of  the  model  advertised.  If  the  customer  insists  that  he  wishes  to  see  the  advertised  model  and 
(sannot  be  interested  in  anything-else,  the  salesman  will  finally  show  him  this  model,  saying  that,  although 
It  is  a  very  good  refrigerator,  it  cannot  be  compared  In  service  and  desirability  to  the  regular  models. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         143 

sumers  preferred  not  to  buy  at  all  rather  than  to  buy  articles  which 
were  indicated  to  be  inferior. 

Much  broader  prospects  of  sales  expansion  than  those  derived  from 
the  introduction  of  these  special  models  would  flow  from  a  general 
reduction  in  prices.  In  other  words,  a  resumption  of  the  price  trends 
which  prevailed  between  1927  and  1932  would,  if  feasible,  be  likely 
to  widen  the  potential  market  materially.  The  precise  degree  of 
expansion  which  might  be  expected  to  reward  any  particular  decline 
in  prices  cannot,  of  course,  be  predicted. 

The  crux  of  the  problem  is  contained  in  the  phrase  "if  feasible." 
Presumably  further  price  reductions  must  reflect  lower  costs.  Broadly 
speaking,  savings  in  cost  may  be  achieved  in  two  directions,  (1)  by 
reducing  costs  of  manufacture,  (2)  by  cutting  the  costs  of  distribution. 

Reductions  in  the  cost  of  manufacturing. — When  interviewed  during 
1939,  manufacturers  in  these  industries  did  not  seem  to  be  especially 
sanguine  as  to  the  prospects  of  materiaUy  reducing  manufacturing 
costs.  In  the  refrigerator  industry,  for  example,  the  smaller  ma,nu- 
facturers  apparently  beheved  that  important  savings  in  manufac- 
turing costs  could  be  initiated  only  by  the  three  or  four  largest  com- 
panies in  the  industry  and  there  was  considerable  doubt  as  to  whether 
such  savings  could  be  possible  even  to  this  restricted  group.  There 
seemed  to  be  some  effort  to  explore  the  possibility  of  achieving  econo- 
mies by  reducing  the  number  of  distinct  models  produced.  The  very 
marked  change  in  the  situation  in  this  industry  since  the  beginning 
of  1940  will  be  discussed  subsequently.^* 

Reduction  of  costs  in  the  manufacture  of  washing  machines  appar- 
ently encoimters  certain  special  obstacles.  Most  producers  in  this 
industry  are  specialized,  producing  washing  and  ironing  machines 
exclusively.  The  industry  is  largely  one  of  machining  and  assemblage. 
Most  of  the  manufacturers  purchase  a  considerable  portion  of  their 
materials  partially  or  wholly  fabricated.^^  Opportunities  to  lower 
the  cost  of  manufacture  are  correspondingly  limited.  However,  one 
or  two  very  large  corporations  have  recently  entered  the  industry; 
this  may  result  in  materially  reduced  production  costs. 

In  the  electric-range  industry,  reductions  in  production  costs  may 
be  expected  to  continue  if  the  volume  of  the  industry's  sales  maintains 
its  present  rate  of  growth.  Members  of  the  industry  confidently  ex- 
pect that  when  the  industry  reaches  a  higher  output  basis,  production 
costs  will  be  materially  below  their  present  level. 

Distribution  costs. — The  foregoing  comments  with  regard  to  manu- 
facturing costs  were  largely  inferential,  since  there  are  few  data  upon 
which  to  base  a  more  informed  appraisal.  Somewhat  more  informa- 
tion is  available  regarding  costs  of  distribution. 

In  general,  the  distributive  margin  in  these  industries  constitutes  a 
very  substantial  fraction  of  the  retail  price.  In  the  case  of  refriger- 
ators, for  example,  the  retail  price  during  the  past  decade  has  con- 
sistently approximated  slightly  more  than  twice  the  manufacturer's 
price.  In  other  words,  between  1928  and  1937,  the  combined  whole- 
sale and  retail  mark-ups  have  slightly  exceeded  50  percent,  measured 

«  See  p.  154  below. 

»  National  Recovery  Act  Code  History,  Washing  and  Ii  oning  Machine  Manufacturing  Industry,  pp.  2, 3. 


144  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

in  terms  of  the  consumers'  list  price.     The  spread  between  factory- 
price  and  retail  price  during  this  period  is  shown  below: 

Table  14. — Distributive  margin  of  electric  refrigerators 


Year 

Average 
factory 

Average 
retail 

Margin 

Year 

A.verage 
factory 

Average 
retail 

Margin 

price' 

price  > 

Actual 

Percent 

price' 

price' 

Actual 

Percent 

Estimated 

Estimated 

Estimated 

Estimated 

1828 

$166 

$334 

$168 

60 

1933 

$83 

$170 

$87 

51 

1929 

134 

292 

168 

64 

1934 

84 

172 

88 

51 

1930 

132 

275 

143 

62 

1935 

78 

166 

88 

53 

1931 

129 

258 

129 

50 

1936 

81 

164 

83 

61 

1932 

101 

196 

94 

48 

1937..— 

86 

173 

88 

51 

1  Source:  National  Electrical  Manufacturers'  Association. 
'  Source:  Air  Conditioning  and  Refrigeration  News. 

During  1938,  the  spread  between  factory  and  retail  prices  for  the 
cheapest  4-foot  models  produced  by  three  important  manufacturers 
ranged  between  $64.62  and  $67.80.  It  is  apparent  that  a  very  mate- 
rial reduction  in  the  retail  price  level  could  have  been  achieved  had  it 
been  feasible  to  reduce  this  distributive  margin. 

Somewhat  the  same  situation  exists  in  the  washing-machine  indus- 
try. One  prominent  producer  operates  on  the  basis  of  the  margins 
shown  in  the  following  table: 

Table  15. — Distributive  margin  of  electric  washing  machines 


Manufac- 
turer's 
price  to  the 
Jobber  i 

Suggested 
price  to  the 
consumer  ' 

Distribu- 
tive 
margin 

Distribu- 
tive 
margin  as 
percent 
of  retail 
price 

Model  A. 

$23. 26 
27.25 
33.76 

$39.95 
49.95 
69.95 

$16.  70 
22.70 
36.20 

41 

Model  B 

46 

Model  0 

52 

» Not  including  freight  charges. 

The  distributive  margin  for  the  highest-priced  washing  machine, 
model  C,  amounted  to  52  percent  of  the  retail  price,  or  approximately 
the  same  ratio  as  that  shown  for  refrigerators.  This  percentage 
represents  the  actual  situation  in  the  industry  more  adequately  than 
do  the  figures  relating  to  the  two  cheaper  models,  since  only  a  minority 
of  sales  fall  into  the  lower  price  brackets.^^ 

"  The  actual  distribution  of  sales  of  electric  washing  machines  in  1938  by  price  classes  is  shown  in  the 
following  table: 

Table  16.— Distribution  of  sales  and  average  value  of  electric  washing  machines  by  price  lines— 19S8 


Retail  price  classes 

Units 

Average 
retail 
price 

Percent 
of  total 

Below$40 

88,916 
161, 002 
450, 077 
331,358 

$36.63 
48."  11 
63.22 

105.  46 

9 

$40  to  $49.99.... 

16 

$50  to  $69.99 

44 

$70  and  over 

32 

Total 

1,031,363 

72.14 

Source:  National  Association  of  Washing  Machine  Manufacturers. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


145 


In  the  vacuum-cleaner  industry  distributive  margins  on  sales  through 
the  orthodox  wholesaler-retailer  channel  are  of  approximately  the 
same  order.  However,  the  house-to-house  canvassing  system  used 
by  some  of  the  leading  companies  is  even  more  costly.  Thus  one 
prominent  vacuum-cleaner  manufacturer,  selling  through  regular 
channels,  was  able  to  offer  his  cleaner  which  cost  him  altogether 
$10.30  to  produce  at  a  retail  price  of  $25,  less  50  percent  discount  to 
the  dealer.  This  allowed  him  a  profit  per  cleaner  of  only  $2.20. 
Thereupon,  he  decided  to  embark  upon  a  program  of  house-to-house 
canvassing.  When  this  system  of  distribution  was  established,  he 
found  that  in  order  to  cover  the  cost  of  canvassing,  he  had  to  raise 
the  retail  price  of  the  cleaner  to  $49. 50.^'' 

A  similar  example  is  cited  by  O.  W.  Blackett: 

The  management  of  Eureka  Vacuum  Cleaner  Co.,  which  had  average  annual 
earnings  of  well  over  a  million  dollars  prior  to  the  depression,  lost  so  heavily  in 
1931  that  it  reconsidered  its  whole  method  of  retail  distribution.  It  has  used 
various  methods  of  promotion,  but  had  inaugurated  a  system  of  direct  sales  to 
consumers  in  1922  which  had  proved  so  successful  that  by  1930,  the  major  part 
of  the  sales  volume  was  obtained  in  that  way.  The  method  was,  however,  very 
expensive  since  it  required  branches  and  subbranches  to  handle  installment-sales 
accounting,  to  care  for  local  advertising,  and  to  carry  a  sufficient  inventory.  The 
decline  in  sales  necessitated  the  cutting  of  expenses,  which  was  accomplished  by 
substituting  dealer  outlets  for  the  company's  own  branches.  It  was  possible  to 
predict  roughly  the  saving  in  expense  througli  elimination  of  branch  offices.  The 
major  uncertainty  was  how  much  reduction  of  sales  volume  would  follow  the  sub- 
stitution of  other  outlets.  The  management  fully  expected  such  a  reduction,  but 
hoped  it  would  be  more  than  balanced  by  the  saving  of  expense.  In  this  instance, 
the  management  made  what  for  the  moment,  at  least,  was  a  wise  decision,  since 
the  change  enabled  them  to  show  a  sizable  profit  on  reduced  volume  in  1932. 
Only  time  will  tell  whether  the  immediate  gain  justified  the  abandonment  of  a 
system  of  distribution  which  had  aided  tht  company  to  increase  its  sales  from  15  5 
percent  of  the  industry  in  1921,  to  27.2  percent  in  1927.  In  very  recent  years 
the  company  has  returned  to  its  former  policy  of  direct  sales  but  to  date  has  not 
regained  the  dominant  position  relinquished  for  the  sake  of  immediate  profits  in 
1932.28 

The  one  important  exception  to  these  high  costs  of  distribution 
relates  to  products  marketed. through  mass  distributors.  The  follow- 
ing table  presents  a  comparison  of  the  costs  of  refrigerators  and  wash- 
ing machines  distributed  through  a  mass  distributor  and  through 
orthodox  retailing  channels. 

Table  17. — Distributive  margins 
[Sales  througb  mass  distributors  and  regular  channels] 


Retail 
price 

Manu- 
facturer's 
cost 

Cost  of  distribution 

Type  of  distribution 

Actual 

Percent 

of  retail 

price 

Refrigerators: 

Typical  standard  brand  sales  orgaoizatlon 

$207.60 
158.00 

155.00 
89.50 

$93. 34- 
100.00 

64.00 
56.00 

$114. 16 
68.00 

91.00 
31.50 

165.0 

Mass  distributor 

36.7 

Washers: 

Typical  standard  brand  sales  organization 

«58.  7 

Mass  distributor 

31.2 

•  However,  the  margins  shown  in  this  table  for  the  orthodox  channel  of  distribution  are  somewhat  higher 
than  those  shown  in  tables  14  and  15  above  (p.  144)  for  the  same  year.  This  dlflerence  may  be  due  to  the  fact 
that  this  table  is  based  upon  comparatively  expensive  models. 

Source:  Compiled  from  Thomas,  John  F.,  Varying  Functions  in  Distribution,  Their  Costs  and  Influences 
on  RetaU  Prices,  Journal  of  Marketing,  July  1938,  p.  6fl. 

"  Rost,  Fred  O.,  Distribution  Today,  1933,  pp.  180, 181. 
"  Economic  Problems  in  a  Changing  World,  a  symposium. 
Rlnehart.  p.  421. 


Edited  by  Willard  Thorp — Farrar  and 


J  46  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

These  figures  illustrate  the  possible  savings  which  may  flow  from 
greater  efl&ciency  in  the  process  of  distribution.  The  distributive 
margin  in  the  case  of  the  company  using  direct  distribution  was  $58; 
for  the  refrigerator  distributed  through  the  regular  channels  the  spread 
amounted  to  $114.16.  In  the  case  of  washing  machines  the  distribu- 
tion cost  for  direct  distribution  is  $31.50;  for  the  product  distributed 
through  the  regular  channels  it  is  $91.  There  is  some  difference  of 
opinion  regarding  the  comparability  of  these  models,  but  this  does  not 
affect  the  contrast  in  distributive  margins. 

In  addition,  the  mass  distributor  sells  a.  vacuum  cleaner  at  $49.50 
which,  according  to  the  company,  is  comparable  with  other  makes 
retailing  at  $79.50.  It  is  claimed  that  the  saving  is  made  possible 
by  its  more  economical  system  of  distribution. 

At  the  present  time,  sales  through  mass  distributors  apparently 
constitute  the  most  aggressive  effort  to  reduce  costs  of  distribution, 
although  at  least  one  other  large  producer  is  endeavoring  to  cut  dealer 
margins.  Jn  fact,  some  members  of  these  industries  have  expressed 
the  opinion  that  distribution  costs  are  already  as  low  as  they  can  be 
brought,  and  that  any  further  reduction  would  result  in  a  loss  of  vital 
sales  outlets,  dealer  cooperation,  and  necessary  advertising. 

Members  of  the  washing-machine  industry  claimed  that  distributive 
margins  in  the  industry  had  not  changed  materially  in  recent  years, 
and  that  their  reduction  could  not  be  expected  in  view  of  the  guarantee 
for  repair  parts  and  of  the  responsibilities  for  servicing  which  the  dealer 
has  assumed. 

In  the  vacuum-clean.er  industry  it  is  said  that  some  of  the  large 
companies  which  are  now  utilizing  house-to-house  canvassing  are 
planning  to  distribute  extensively  through  ordinary  channels.  How- 
ever, unless  the  canvassing  technique  is  largely  abandoned,  it  is  un- 
likely that  any  savings  in  cost  due  to  the  partial  utilization  of  regular 
channels  will  be  translated  into  lower  prices  to  the  consumer.  It  would 
be  impractical  for  a  company  to  charge  different  prices  for  its  product 
when  sold  by  a  visiting  salesman  and  by  a  retail  store.  It  seems  prob- 
able, therefore,  that  the  prices  charged  on  store  sales  will  be  maintained 
at  the  same  level  as  those  on  house-to-house  sales,  and  that  that  level 
will  be  largely  determined  by  the  costs  of  the  latter  system. 

It  is  apparent,  consequently,  that  there  have  been  obstacles  to  any 
program  of  extensive  price  reductions  in  these  industries,  whether  such 
reductions  applied  to  the  manufacturer's  price  or  to  the  distributor's 
margin.  During  1939  most  manufacturers  in  these  industries  appar- 
ently believed  that  the  era  of  price  reductions  had  terminated  and  that 
further  cuts  in  price  would  not  be  rewarded  by  a  sufficient  increase  in 
volume  to  make  the  venture  profitable.  Thus,  it  has  been  mentioned 
that  the  smaller  refrigerator  manufacturers  believed  that  only  the 
largest  members  of  the  industry,  comprising  corporations  which  had 
extensive  interests  outside  the  refrigerator  industry,  could  afford  to 
take  the  risks  incurred  in  any  material  change  in  price  policy. 

On  the  other  hand,  there  has  been  increasing  awareness  among  both 
manufacturers  and  distributors  that  the  price  element  is  becoming 
increasingly  important  as  the  market  among  families  in  the  more 
prosperous  income  levels  is  becoming  saturated.  As  early  as  the 
spring  of  1939  one  large  manufacturer  had  become  convinced  of  the 
need   for  lower  prices.     An   editorial  in  Electrical  Merchandising, 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  147 

published  in  January  1937,  expressed  this  point  of  view  even  before 
the  sharp  contraction  in  sales  which  forcibly  focused  attention  upon 
the  problem. 

Electrical  distributing  trades,  both  wholesale  and  retail,  may  eoon  be  forced  to 
face  the  problem  of  justifying  markets.  Wholesalers  and  retailers  have  always 
upheld  the  need  for  more  margin,  although  they  agree  over-all  distribution  costs 
are  high.  Now  a  question  as  to  whether  retailers  and  wholesalers  are  performing  a 
service  equivalent  to  their  remuneration.  Costs  in  1937  are  bound  to  increase 
because  of  rising  costs  of  raw  materials  and  demand  for  higher  wages.  But 
manufacturers  a're  faced  with  the  necessity  of  keeping  prices  down.  A  survey 
indicated  42  percent  of  refrigerator  business  in  1938  will  come  from  lower-income 
families,  a  market  definitely  conditioned  by  lower  prices.  Yet,  it  is  possible  that 
appliance  prices  may  be  forced  up.  Profit  from  present  market — a  market  dis- 
tinguished from  former  years  by  higher  costs  and  lower  prices — can  be  in  some  part 
derived  from  greater  production  efiiciency.  But  there  is  the  question  as  to  how 
much  further  manufacturing  efficiency  can  be  increased;  this  leaves  only  distribu- 
tion expense  to  be  trimmed,  and  manufacturers  are  asking  if  it  is  possible  to  reduce 
by  some  percent  the  present  high  cost  of  distribution. 

Difference  between  manufacturing  cost  and  selling  price  is  high — for  many 
appliances  the  cost  of  selling  is  two-thirds  or  more  of  total  retail  value. 

Wholesalers  have  given  much  study  to  reducing  operating  costs.  Chains 
already  claim  efficiency  and  savings  to  the  public,  but  independent  retailers  have 
given  little  study  to  operating  costs  and  possible  savings  *  *  *_  Qur  guess  is 
that  distribution  costs  are  in  for  an  acute  scrutiny. 

The  same  periodical  later  (1938)  published  letters  from  appliance 
dealers  which  revealed  their  concern  with  the  problem,  and  particu- 
larly with  the  competition  offered  by  low-cost  mass  distributors: 

Appliance  business  will  be  more  efi'ectively  and  profitably  handled  when — 
manufacturers  sell  direct  to  dealers  and  eliminate  jobber  on  several  lines  and  on 
other  lines — such  jobbers  who  now  exist  should  be  converted  into  direct-selling 
retail  specialty  companies. 

From  18  to  20  percent  margin  is  now  being  absorbed  by  distribution  or  those 
endeavoring  to  sell  to  the  dealers — which  amount  of  percentage  should  come  to  the 
retail  distributor  to  use  for  direct  sale  promotion. 

And— 

All  manufacturers  keep  prices  up  knowing  dealers  have  to  have  long  margin, 
the  general  public  compare  all  standard  makes  with  catalog  houses,  which  is  from 
$10  to  $15  lower.  Catalog  houses  get  the  deal  and  consumer  does  not  mention 
his  old  trade-in,  so  I  am  heartily  in  favor  of  taking  smaller  percentage  of  profit, 
provided  distributor  and  manufacturer  will  lower  their  profits.  This,  I  think,  is 
only  way  you  can  lick  catalog  competition.  (Electrical  Merchandising,  The 
Appliance  Dealer,  1938.) 

Obviouslj'-  this  awareness  of  the  problem  must  be  somehow  trans- 
lated into  a  positive  program  for  reducing  prices  if  the  market  among 
lower  income  groups  is  to  be  widened  appreciably.  Until  1940, 
however,  there  was  no  concrete  evidence  of  such  a  trend,  except  for 
that  provided  by  a  few  mass  distributory  organizations.  Their 
relatively  low  cost  of  distribution  permits  them  to  compete  on  a  price 
basis.  As  a  result,  their  share  of  the  market  has  expanded  materially. 
Between  1932  and  1937,  sales  of  the  lower  priced  equipment  by  mass 
distributors  increased  four  times  as  fast  as  sales  for  the  industry  as  a 
whole.  It  is  also  noteworthy  that  the  decline  experienced  by  mass 
distributors  during  the  1937-38  recession  amounted  to  only  one-half 
as  much  as  that  of  the  entire  industry.  The  success  achieved  by  these 
concerns  merely  demonstrated  the  efficacy  of  low  prices  as  a  sales 
argument  and  emphasized  the  need  of  serious  attention  to  the  problem 
by  the  concerns  utilizing  regular  channels. 


148 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


THE    REPLACEMENT    MARKET 


Need  jor  considering  the  replacement  market. — The  second  majoi 
avenue  of  sales  expansion  for  these  electrical-appUance  mdustries  is 
the  stimulation  of  the  replacement  market.  For  any  industry  pro- 
ducing consumers'  durable  goods,  the  replacement  of  worn-out  or 
obsolescent  merchandise  necessarily  constitutes  an  ever-increasing 
share  of  the  market  as  the  industry  matures.  In  fact,  it  is  this  pro- 
gressive shift  from  original  sales  to  replacement  sales  which  con- 
stitutes the  basic  significance  of  market  saturation.  It  is  obvious 
that  the  mere  fact  that  a  family  already  possesses  a  refrigerator  or 
washing  machine  or  a  vacuum  cleaner  does  not  automatically  elimi- 
nate that  family  from  consideration  as  a  sales  prospect  for  a  new 
model.  On  the  other  hand,  the  considerations  which  will  determine 
such  a  family's  decision  to  buy  are  in  many  ways  different  from  those 
relating  to  original  prospects.  Consequently  a  program  designed  to 
stimulate  replacement  sales  must  give  due  weight  to  these  differences. 

Moreover,  it  should  be  emphasized  that  the  development  of  the 
replacement  market  is  not  to  be  considered  merely  as  an  alternative  in 
case  it  should  not  prove  feasible  to  extend  original  sales  among  fami- 
lies in  the  lower  income  brackets.  Regardless  of  the  success  of  the 
latter  course,  the  replacement  problem  will  be  of  growing  importance. 
The  consequences  of  saturation  may  be  temporarily  minimized  or 
avoided  by  altering  price  policies  so  as  to  widen  the  number  of  original 
prospects,  but  eventually  they  must  be  met  notwithstanding.  In 
other  words,  a  shift  from  original  to  replacement  sales  is  inherent  in 
the  very  nature  of  consumers'  durable-goods  markets. 

Extent  of  replacement  sales. — The  outstanding  example  of  an  in- 
dustry whose  market  has  largely  shifted  from  an  original  to  a  replace- 
ment basis  is  the  automobile  industry.  As  far  back  as  1926,  73  per- 
cent of  all  new  passenger  car  sales  were  accompanied  by  trade-ins; 
that  is,  they  involved  the  replacement  of  an  older  model.  Since  1929 
this  ratio  has  increased  further;  in  1937  approximately  88  percent  of 
all  new  passenger  car  sales  were  for  replacement. 

In  the  electrical-appliance  industries  the  ratio  is  not  nearly  so  high 
as  yet.  However,  it  is  increasing  rapidly.  The  trend  of  replacement 
sales  as  a  percent  of  all  sales  in  the  electric-refrigerator  industry  is 
shown  in  the  table  below.  The  data  are  for  two  leading  refrigerator 
manufacturers;  they  seem  sufficiently  parallel  to  be  considered 
indicative  of  the  general  trend  in  the  industry. 

Table  18. — Replacement  sales  as  a  percent  of  total  sales  of  electric  refrigerators 


Year 

Company 
A 

Company 

Year 

Company  Company 
A                3 

1 

1929 - 

3 
2 
3 

1 
3 

1934 __- 

1935          ...             

9 
10 
13 
15 
19 

7 

1930 

10 

1931 - 

1936 

1937. 

14 

1932  .     .     

1 

2 

16 

1933 

1938 

18 

The  ratio  rose  particularly  sharply  from  1933  to  1934.  Since  the 
latter  year  it  has  increased  steadily.  For  the  year  1938,  the  figures 
of  these  two  companies  are  slightly  below  an  estimate  made  by  Air 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


149 


Conditioning  and  Refrigeration  News.  This  estimate,  based  upon 
reports  of  manufacturers,  distributors,  and  dealers,  indicates  that 
about  20  percent  of  the  United  States  sales  of  household  electric 
refrigerators  during  1938  involved  the  replacement  of  a  unit  pre- 
viously used  by  the  same  family.^^ 

In  the  washing-machine  industry  it  is  estimated  that  the  ratio  of 
replacement  to  total  sales  is  currently  as  high  as  46.3  percent.^"  For 
vacuum  cleaners,  the  replacement  ratio  is  believed  to  be  between  35 
and  40  percent. 

Factors  influencing  replacement  sales. — In  any  program  designed  to 
stimulate  replacement  sales  as  a  means  of  expanding  the  market  for 
these  products  it  is  necessary  to  emphasize  the  specific  considerations 
surrounding  the  replacement  market.  It  has  been  pointed  out  that 
the  factors  which  would  induce  prospective  purchasers  to  replace 
used  equipment  are  in  many  ways  distinct  from  those  governing  the 
original  market.  These  specific  considerations  may  be  conveniently 
grouped  into  three  categories,  (a)  durability,  (6)  obsolescence,  and 
(c)  trade-in  allowances  as  affecting  the  cost  of  replacement.  These 
will  be  considered  consecutively. 

Durability. — The  importance  of  durability  is  apparent.  When  a 
product  is  worn  out  so  completely  that  it  is  either  useless  or  extremely 
expensive  to  operate,  its  replacement  can  no  longer  be  delayed.  In- 
creases in  durability,  such  as  have  characterized  these  appliances 
during  recent  years,  may  to  some  extent  be  expected  to  retard  re- 
placement. For  example,  the  increase  in  the  life  expectancy  of  the 
average  electric  refrigerator  is  shown  in  the  following  table: 

Table  19. — Estimated  durability  of  electric  refrigerators 


Year  of  manufacture: 

Life  expectancy  (years)  ' 

Year  of  manufacture: 

Life  expectancy  (years) 

1920 

6 

1930 

13 

1921 

7 

1931 

.     13 

1922 

8 

1932 

13 

1923 

9 

1933 

13 

1924 

10 

1934 

14 

1925 

11 

1935 

14 

1926 

11 

1936 

14 

1927 

12 

1937 

15 

1928 

12 

1938 

15 

1929 

._. 12 

1  The  figure  for  each  year  is  an  average  of  data  compiled  from  a  sample  study  which  was  made  by  a  large 
manufacturer  of  refrigerators. 

Similarly,  there  is  evidence  that  the  durability  of  washing  machines 
and  vacuum  cleaners  has  been  increasing.  Thus,  according  to  the 
Secretary  of  the  Association  of  American  Washing  Machine  Manufac- 
turers, a  modern  machine  will,  with  reasonable  care,  last  at  least  10 
years.  The  Secretary  of  the  Vacuum  Cleaner  Manufacturers  Associa- 
tion estimates  that  the  average  life  expectancy  of  a  cleaner  is  approxi- 
mately 12  years  today,  in  contrast  to  only  6  years  for  a  1929  model. 
This  trend  conforms  with  the  concept  that  it  is  not  in  the  public 
interest  to  reduce  durability  in  order  to  sell  more  appliances  unless 
there  is  a  marked  decline  in  prices;  even  then  it  may  be  undesirable. 

Obsolescence. — However,    the    importance    of    absolute    durability 

"  Air  Conditioning  and  Refrigeration  News,  Januar.y  1939. 
"  Electrical  Merchandising,  The  Appliance  Dealer,  1938. 


^5Q  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

may  readily  be  overemphasized.  Although  some  owners  will  continue 
to  use  products  of  this  kind  until  their  utility  is  entirely  destroyed, 
the  introduction  of  more  efficient  or  more  attractive  products  often 
results  in  inducing  replacements  long  before  the  article  in  use  has 
become  completely  worn  out. 

The  persuasiveness  of  obsolescence  in  stimulating  replacement 
varies  with  the  nature  of  the  product.  In  the  automobile  industry, 
for  example,  changes  in  style  are  apparently  of  far  more  importance  m 
determining  the  rate  of  replacement  than  is  durability  as  such.  As 
far  as  durability  is  concerned,  there  has  apparently  been  a  distinct 
lengthening  of  actual  car  life  during  the  last  10  or  15  years.  Thus, 
studies  of  cars  in  use  in  1926  and  1935  show  that,  whereas  in  the 
former  year  50  percent  of  the  cars  survived  between  6  and  7  years, 
in  the  latter  year  50  percent  survived  about  9  years.^^  Yet,  despite 
this  increase  in  durability,  frequent  changes  in  style  and  improve- 
ments in  comfort  and  lower  operating  costs  have  resulted  in  maintain- 
ing replacements  at  a  high  rate. 

Conditions  with  regard  to  obsolescence  in  the  appUance  industries 
are  not  entirely  analogous  to  those  in  the  automobile  industry.  It  is 
doubtful,  for  example,  that  the  desire  to  own  the  latest  model  of 
refrigerator  can  ever  be  quite  as  impelling  as  the  wish  to  display  the 
newest  style  of  automobile.  Nevertheless,  according  to  an  official 
of  a  leading  refrigerator  manufacturing  company : 

In  America,  Mrs.  Housewife  will  insist  on  buying  a  new  electric  refrigerator  a 
couple  of  years  after  she  bought  her  last  one,  because  the  new  refrigerators  are 
streamlined,  more  efficient,  or  decorated  in  delphinium  blue  or  have  some  new 
trick  gadgets  '2  .  .  .  Therefore,  in  all  our  thoughts  on  saturation,  don't  let  us 
forget  that  the  American  public  will  always  continue  to  discard  their  electrical 
devices  long  before  they  have  worn  out,  and  buy  new  ones  provided,  of  course, 
we  manufacturers  can  keep  on  changing  the  models  and  our  utility  and  dealer 
friends  aggressively  point  out  the  new  advantages  to  the  public.^' 

Moreover,  the  same  official  suggested  that  the  tendency  of  operating 
costs  to  increase  after  a  few  years  of  operation  might  constitute  an 
added  inducement  to  early  replacement. 

These  considerations  have  their  obvious  limitations  and  there  is 
evidence  that  the  viewpoint  expressed  above  is  by  no  means  unani- 
mously held  in  the  industry.  Nevertheless,  changes  in  style^  or  in 
mechanical  features  will,  to  a  limited  extent,  stimulate  the  desire  for 
replacement.  In  the  case  of  such  products  as  washing  machines  and 
vacuum  cleaners,  mere  changes  in  appearance  can  probably  have  little 
if  any  effect.  Neither  of  these  products  is  a  display  piece;  their 
purpose  is  purely  utilitarian.  Obsolescence  must,  therefore,  be 
induced  by  basic  changes  in  operating  features  rather  than  in  appear- 
ance. The  new  "all  purpose"  washing  machine  and  the  tank  type  of 
cleaner  may  represent  this  type  of  major  technical  improvement. 

Cost  of  replacement — The  trade-in  allowance. — Assuming  a  desire  on 
the  part  of  an  owner  to  replace  obsolescent  equipment,  a  basic  con- 
sideration determining  his  decision  is  obviously  the  question  of  cost. 
The  cost  of  making  a  replacement  is  dependent  not  only  upon  the 
price  of  the  new  product  but  also  upon  the  allowance  granted  by  the 
dealer  for  the  used  article.  High  trade-in  allowances  will  obviously 
stimulate  replacements — low  allowances  will  discourage  them. 

"  The  Dj  namics  of  Automobile  Demand,  General  Motors  Corporation,  New  York,  N.  Y.,  1939,  pp.  47-49. 
"  Seme  n  anufacturers,  however,  question  the  efBcacy  of  this  technique  of  Inducing  rapid  replacement. 
"  Quoted  In  Printers'  Ink  Monthly,  August  1937. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  151 

Probably  the  outstanding  feature  of  the  automobile  industry's  re- 
placement policy  is  the  highly  developed  character  of  the  used  car  mar- 
ket. Trade-ins  are  accepted  by  dealers  as  a  matter  of  course.  On  sales 
of  new  vehicles,  the  automobile  turned  in  by  the  new  car  buyer  is,  in 
turn,  resold  and  on  that  resale  there  "is  usually  another  trade-in. 
During  1937,  trade-ins  were  accepted  on  88  percent  of  new  car  sales 
and  on  56  percent  of  used  car  sales. ^^  Used  car  values  have  become 
well  standardized.  What  is  perhaps  most  important  is  the  fact  that 
these  allowances  are  sufficiently  high  to  induce  most  car  buyers  to 
replace  their  automobiles  after  only  2  or  3  years  of  use.^^ 

In  general,  although  the  acceptance  of  trade-ins  on  the  sale  of 
electrical  household  equipment  is  becoming  increasingly  common,  the 
market  has  not  yet  reached  the  highly  organized  state  of  that  existing 
in  the  automobile  industry.  Nor  are  the  allowances  granted  usually 
as  liberal.  A  comparison  of  the  percentages  of  the  retail  list  price 
allowed  for  popular  priced  automobiles  and  for  refrigerators  of  differ- 
ent ages  is  shown  in  table  23. 

For  a  1937  automobile,  the  trade-in  allowance  was  approximately 
50  percent  of  the  original  price  whereas  for  a  refrigerator  of  the 
same  age  the  allowance  is  only  32  percent.  This  same  type  of  diver- 
gence applies  to  most  of  the  older  models. 

In  the  case  of  washing  machines  it  is  understood  that  the  trade-in 
allowance  on  recent  models  usually  ranges  from  25  to  35  percent  of 
the  list  price.  Often  this  allowance  is  fixed  regardless  of  the  type, 
make,  or  condition  of  the  machine  offered  in  trade. 

For  vacuum  cleaners,  the  allowance  is  generally  about  25  percent 
of  the  list  price  but  rarely  exceeds  $15  for  any  model. 

Actual  allowances  on  any  specific  sale  are  of  course  determined  by 
the  dealer.  Consequently,  these  figures  must  be  considered  merely  as 
approximations.  They  serve  to  show,  however,  that  the  amount 
which  an  owner  of  used  equipment  can  expect  to  recover  on  a  trade-in 
is  materially  smaller  for  these  electrical  appliances  than  is  true  in  the 
case  of  automobiles.  Since  it  is  this  allowance  which  determines  the 
actual  outlay  required  for  replacement,  it  is  apparent  that  the  induce- 
ment offered  to  o  ,vners  of  used  equipment  to  change  for  new  models  is 
correspondingly  lower. 

To  some  extent  these  differences  between  the  equipment  industries 
and  the  automobile  industry  reflect  differences  in  distributive  mark- 
ups. The  average  retail  mark-up  for  a  popular  priced  automobile  is 
only  25  percent  of  the  retail  list  price  as  compared  with  about  40 
percent  for  refrigerators  and  washing  machines.  It  is  evident  that  a 
dealer  is  unlikely  to  grant  an  allowance  for  used  equipment  exceeding 
the  cost  to  him  for  new  equipment.  Consequently,  as  soon  as  a 
refrigerator,  for  example,  has  passed  from  the  retailer  to  the  consumer 
it  has  suffered  an  immediate  depreciation  equivalent  to  at  least  the 
amount  of  the  retail  mark-up.  In  this  way,  high  distributive  margins 
not  only  restrict  the  original  market  by  increasing  the  retail  price; 
they  simultaneously  discourage  replacements  by  limiting  trade-in 
allowances. 

'<  Automobile  Facts  and  Fipures,  1938  edition,  p.  67. 

"  Trade-in  markets  have  also  become  established  in  other  industries.  In  the  agricultural  machinery 
Industry,  for  example,  a  recent  survey  by  a  leading  producer  showed  that  out  of  a  total  sale  of  nearly  9,000 
machines,  by  50  dealers,  trade-ins  were  taken  on  over  ."JiOOO  machines.  Moreover,  the  bulk  of  the  machines 
on  which  there  were  no  trade-ins  were  of  relatively  small  size,  such  as  knife  grinders,  walking  plows,  etc. 
Eighty-two  percent  of  tractor  sales  involve  trade-ins  of  various  kinds. 

247149—41 — No.  1 12 


3^52  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  second  factor  governing  the  character  of  the  trade-in  market 
is  the  disposition  of  the  used  models  turned  in.  This  disposition,  of 
CQurse,  depends  to  a  considerable  extent  upon  the  condition  of  the 
used  equipment.  Some  of  it  is  unfit  for  future  use.  Even  in  the 
automobile  industry  some  of  the  cars  received  from  trade  must  be 
junked,  though  the  proportion  is  very  low.  (During  1937  less  than 
8  percent  of  all  trade-ins  were  junked.)^^ 

In  the  electrical-appliance  industries  the  ratio  of  junked  equipment 
is  materially  higher.  A  survey  conducted  during  January  1938, 
covering  820  independent  dealers  scattered  throughout  the  Nation, 
showed  that  about  one-fourth  of  all  used  refrigerators  taken  in  trade 
was  considered  unfit  for  resale.  In  the  case  of  washing  machines  the 
percentage  was  even  higher.  According  to  the  same  survey,  41  per- 
cent of  used  washers  were  jimked.^^  For  vacuum  cleaners  the  ratio 
was  also  about  40  percent. 

These  relatively  high  ratios  reveal,  in  part,  the  tendency  of  many 
owners  of  electrical  household  appliances  to  postpone  their  replace- 
ment until  the  equipment  has  bocoDie  completely  worn  out.  In 
addition,  dealers  in  these  industries  are  possibly  not  as  well  equipped 
to  recondition  used  equipment  as  arc  automobile  dealers,  who  usually 
maintain  complete  service  stations  in  connection  with  their  salesrooms. 

Allowances  granted  on  equipment  whose  destination  is  the  junk 
yard  merely  constitute  price  concessions,  indicating  a  willingness  on 
the  part  of  the  retail  dealer  to  forego  part  of  his  margin  in  order  to 
make  the  sale.  To  an  extent  the  original  equipment  may  be  over- 
priced in  order  to  meet  just  this  situation. 

However,  the  majority  of  equipment  accepted  in  trade  is  resold 
either  with  or  without  reconditioning.  In  the  case  of  refrigerators, 
approximately  44  percent  of  total  used  equipment  received  is  resold 
"as  is"  while  32  percent  is  reconditioned.  In  the  case  of  washing 
machines  30  percent  is  sold  as  is  and  29  percent  reconditioned.^^ 

The  amount  which  may  be  recovered  by  the  dealer  on  resale  of 
second-hand  equipment  is  affected  by  the  manner  in  which  it  is  recon- 
ditioned. This  resale  price,  together  with  the  cost  of  reconditioning, 
are  in  turn  important  elements  in  determining  the  trade-in  allowance 
which  may  be  extended. 

Facilities  for  reconditioning  equi'pment—the  Crosley  plan. — It  has 
been  pointed  out  that  many  electrical-equipmeat  dealers,  in  contrast 
to  automobile  dealers,  do  not  possess  the  service  facilities  needed  for 
efficient  and  economical  reconditioning.  Recently,  however,  several 
efforts  have  been  made  to  remedy  this  deficiency. 

For  example,  an  experimental  policy  was  recently  adopted  by  the 
Crosley  Co.  This  policy  covers  nine  models,  seven  of  1937  and  tv/o 
of  1938.  A  list  of  national  trade-in  allowances  has  been  established 
for  these  nine  models.  Dealers  receiving  Crosley  refrigerators  on 
trade-ins  may  have  the  units  reconditioned  in  the  service  department 
for  two-thirds  of  the  price  registered  in  the  standard  trade-in  schedule. 
Refrigerators  other  than  Crosley  may  be  reconditioned  by  an  organiza- 
tion known  as  the  General  Refrigerator  Sales  &  Service  Co.  for  a  flat 
fee  of  $20,  or  may  be  sold  to  this  organization  for  one-half  of  the 
listed  trade-in  price.     A  90-day  warranty  is  offered  with  the  rebuilt 

'"  Automobile  Facts  and  Figures,  1938  edition,  p.  67. 

"  Electrical  Merchandising,  The  Appliance  Dealer,  1938. 

>8  Ibid. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  153 

units,  but  only  "reasonably  operative"  boxes  will  be  accepted  for 
reconditioning.  One-half  of  the  pick-up  cost  of  the  old  refrigerator 
will  be  borne  by  the  Crosley  distributing  company  and  the  other  by 
the  dealer.  The  national  trade-in  allowances  as  announced  under  the 
plan  range  from  approximately  one-sixth  to  one-fourth  of  the  list 
price  of  the  various  models. ^^ 

The  Philadelphia  plan. — In  Philadelphia  an  independent  company 
knouTi  as  the  Associated  Refrigerator  Plant,  Inc.,  has  been  organized. 
This  organization  is  equipped  to  recondition  300  used  refrigerators  a 
week  and  is  said  to  be  the  only  plant  in  the  United  States  offering 
reconditioning  service  on  such  a  scale.  Under  its  agreement  with 
dealers,  the  plant  will  recondition  all  types  of  refrigerators  in  one- 
door  models  up  to  10  cubic  feet  at  a  flat  price  of  $20.  This  fee  includes 
free  service  on  the  miits  for  a  period  of  90  days  from  the  time  they  are 
installed  for  new  users.  Where  the  dealer  does  not  desire  to  have 
the  traded-in  refrigerator  reconditioned  for  resale,  the  company  will 
purchase  the  refrigerator  from  him  for  one-half  the  listed  trade-in 
price.  In  this  way,  the  firni  points  out,  dealers  who  trade  for  used 
refrigerators  may  either  have  them  reconditioned  at  a  flat  rate  for 
resale,  or  may  dispose  of  them  directly  to  the  firm  itself. 

Reconditioning  exchange  system  in  vacuum  cleaners. — Large  vacuum 
cleaner  manufacturers  have  an  interchange  agreement  on  replaced 
equipment.  Instead  of  attempting  to  recondition  machines  of  another 
make,  each  manufacturer  exchanges  the  trade-ins  to  the  original  man- 
ufacturer where  the  reconditioning  is  done.  In  addition,  there  are 
quite  a  number  of  small  concerns  loiown  to  the  industry  as  "fly  by 
night"  reconditioners.  These  companies  purchase  old  cleaners  at 
very  low  prices,  recondition  them — often  it  is  said  inadequately — and 
then  resell  them. 

Summary. — Regardless  of  whether  these  specific  efforts  are  successful, 
they  are  significant  of  the  growing  concern  of  these  industries  with  the 
replacement  market.  They  are  also  important  as  demonstrating  the 
probability  that  some  steps  can  be  taken  to  handle  the  trade-in  prob- 
lem more  efl"ectively  than  has  been  the  rule  in  the  past. 

Moreover,  the  very  fact  that  the  major  fraction  of  the  used  equip- 
ment received  in  trade  can  be  resold  with  or  without  reconditioning  is 
evidence  of  the  possibility  of  expanding  the  replacement  market.  It  is 
apparent  that  many  owners  of  these  kinds  of  equipment  will  not  con- 
tinue to  use  them  until  they  are  completely  worn  out  before  contem- 
plating replacement.  Obsolescence  is  a  factor  which  must  be  con- 
sidered. 

Any  program  designed  to  expand  the  replacement  market  materially 
must  be  basically  concerned  with  the  question  of  allowances.  The  less 
expensive  it  becomes  to  exchange  equipment  for  new  models,  the  more 
rapid  will  such  turnover  be,  and  the  larger  the  potential  scope  of  the 
market.  In  turn,  the  used  equipment  which  is  received  in  trade  can 
be  reconditioned  and  resold  to  families  of  lower-income  brackets  who 
cannot  afford  to  pay  the  prices  demanded  for  new  equipment.  This 
does  not  mean  that  there  is  any  probability  that  the  rate  of  replace- 
ment for  electrical  household  appliances  can  be  made  to  approach  that 
of  automobiles.  Nevertheless,  it  does  seem  that  it  can  be  stimulated 
materially  beyond  the  present  rate. 

"  Air  Conditioning  and  Refrigeration  News,  October  20,  1838,  vol.  25,  No.  8. 


J54  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

CURRENT    TRENDS    IN    THE    ELECTRICAL-REFRIGERATOR    INDUSTRY 

During  the  early  months  of  1940  a  major  change  in  price  structure 
occurred  in  the  electrical-refrigerator  industry.  In  the  second  week 
of  January  the  Nash-Kelvinator  Corporation  presented  its  1940  models 
at  prices  which  were  substantially  lower  than  its  1939  quotations.  In 
the  announcement  accompanying  these  reductions  major  prominence 
was  given  to  a  6-foot  stripped  model  offered  at  a  retail  price  of  $119.95 
delivered  east  of  the  Rocky  Mountains.  This  was  the  lowest  price 
ever  quoted  for  a  comparable  model  by  any  leading  manufacturer 
utilizing  the  traditional  wholesaler-retaUer  system  of  distribution.  It 
was  well  below  the  $129-$  134  level  which  the  other  leading  companies 
had  earlier  announced  for  competing  lines.  Moreover,  the  new  price 
was  not  far  above  that  quoted  by  large  mail-order  companies  for  their 
6-foot  stripped  models. 

This  action  by  the  Nash-Kelvinator  Corporation  precipitated  a 
wave  of  similar  reductions  by  its  competitors.  General  Motors, 
General  Electric,  and  Westinghouse,  among  the  larger  companies, 
all  offered  comparable  6-foot  stripped  models  at  a  consumer's  list  price 
of  $114.75  delivered  in  the  zone  nearest  their  respective  plants.  In 
each  case  this  involved  substantial  reductions  below  the  prices  which 
had  been  previously  announced  for  1940. 

Companies  which  had  been  selling  at  levels  below  those  of  the 
"Big  Five"  also  lowered  their  prices.  The  Crosley  Corporation  re- 
duced the  price  of  its  6-foot  stripped  model  and  also  cut  the  prices  of 
its  other  models.  Sears,  Roebuck  offered  its  stripped  6-foot  model 
at  $89.95  and  reduced  the  price  of  its  de  luxe  6-foot  model  from  $139.50 
to  $129.50.  To  meet  these  new  reductions  Nash-Kelvinator,  in  turn, 
announced  another  6-foot  stripped  model  for  $114.75.  Some  of  the 
other  leading  companies  thereupon  cut  prices  further  to  $112.75. 

Other  changes  in  price  structure  were  made  simultaneously.  For 
example,  the  Nash-Kelvinator  Corporation  discarded  its  former  zone 
system  and  is  now  selling  refrigerators  on  a  delivered  basis  anywhere 
east  of  the  Rocky  Mountains.  The  Norge  division  of  the  Norge- 
Warner  Corporation  is  offering  an  all-porcelain  refrigerator  at  $159.95, 
a  figure  which  is  said  to  be  considerably  below  that  of  any  other  all- 
porcelain  model.  The  Philco  Corporation  is  presenting  a  7-foot 
refrigerator  retailing  at  $119.95,  instead  of  the  usual  6-foot  model. 

In  order  to  reduce  costs  to  correspond  with  these  new  prices,  econ- 
omies were  sought  in  both  manufacturing  and  distribution.  One 
method  utilized  has  been  a  reduction  in  the  number  of  different  sizes 
of  box  produced.  Thus,  the  Nash-Kelvinator  Corporation  has  con- 
centrated its  1940  production  on  6-  and  8-cubic-foot  models,  a  policy 
which,  according  to  its  officials,  has  resulted  in  important  savings  in 
costs. 

At  the  same  time,  this  company  eliminated  many  of  its  dealer  out- 
lets in  an  effort  to  cut  the  costs  of  distribution.  Although  dealers' 
margins  remained  unchanged  in  terms  of  percentage,  the  lower  price 
level  involved  a  corresponding  reduction  in  the  actual  dollar  margin 
on  each  unit  sold. 

For  most  companies  the  widest  price  reductions  have  been  for  the 
stripped  6-foot  model  (now  generally  retailing  between  $112.75  and 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


155 


$114.75).  On  other  5-  and  6-foot  models  the  reduction  from  the  1939 
price  is  considerably  narrower.  This  is  indicated  in  table  20,  which 
compares  1939  and  1940  prices  for  a  number  of  leading  companies. 


Table  20. — Retail  published  list  prices  of  electrical  refrigerators,  1939  and  1940 
{delivered,  Washington,  D.  C.) 


NORGE 


1939 

1940 

Model 

Cubic 
feet 

Price 

Model 

Cubic 
feet 

Price 

Q3 ., 

3.25 

4.22 
5.19 
5.25 
5.07 
6.11 
6.11 
6.18 
6.07 
8.25 
8.08 

$119.95 

146. 95 
172.  95 
194.  95 
219.  95 
149. 95 
189.  95 
219.95 
249. 95 
259. 95 
299.95 

VR3S 

3.25 
3.33 
4.22 
6.62 
6.62 

$119  95 

VR3 

119  95 

G4 

VR4 

144.95 

G5 

DR5 

197  50 

N5 

SR5 

219  95 

S5 

UR6 

Sp  c.  6... 

159  95 

Q6 

MR6    . 

6.75 
6.65 
6.65 

8.75 
8.75 

189  95 

M6-.. 

DR6 

219. 96 

S6 

SR6 

244.95 

MS 

DR8 

249.95 

S8 

SR8- 

279.95 

WESTINQHOUSE 


U3 

2.90 
3.25 
4.25 
6.25 
6.25 
5.25 
6.25 
8.25 
13.50 
20.10 
5.25 
6.25 
8.25 
13.50 
20.10 

6.20 

22.70 
24.80 
39.  80 

$119.50 
119.50 
146. 00 
171.50 
190.00 
192. 50 
217.00 
254.00 
419.  50 
489. 50 
213.  50 
242.00 
280.00 
469. 50 
549.  50 

159.  50 

440.00 
695.00 
785.00 

U3      

2.90 

5.25 
6.25 
5.25 
6.25 
8.25 
13.50 
20.10 

6.25 
8.25 
13.50 
20.10 
3.25 
4.25 
6.20 
6.20 
8.25 
6.25 
8.25 

$119  76 

H3 

H5 

H4 

H5 

169  75 

H6 

H6 

179  76 

A5 

A5 

189  75 

A6 

A6 

204  75 

AS.-. 

A8 

254  00 

A135... 

A135 

419  50 

A200 

A200     .  . 

489  50 

E5 

E6       ..  . 

E6 

234  50 

E8 

E8  .. 

279  50 

E135 

E135 

469  50 

E200 

E200 

549.50 

S3. 

119. 75 

S4 

129.76 

LS6 

114  75 

S6 

S6  . 

139  75 

S8 

179.  75 

D6 

224.75 

WF25_. 

D8 

264.75 

A2525R 

A4025R.... .... 

KELVINATOR 


KS3... 
KS4... 
K4.... 
KS5... 
K5.... 
PK5... 
Spec.  6 
KS6... 

K6 

PK6... 

Kg 

PK8... 


3.25 

$119.  50 

4.20 

144.60 

4.20 

159.50 

5.30 

169.50 

5.20 

187.50 

5.20 

209.50 

6.20 

149.50 

6.20 

187.50 

6.20 

212.50 

6.20 

237.60 

8.24 

254.50 

8.24 

282.50 

SS6. 
S6... 
HS6. 
R6.. 
HD6 
S8-.. 
R8.. 
HD8 


j56  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  20. — Retail  published  list  prices  of  electrical  refrigerators,  1939  and  1940 
{delivered,  Washington,  D.  C.) — Continued 

FRIGIDAIRE 


1939 

1940 

Model 

Cubic 
feet 

Price 

$119.50 
139.50 
159.  50 
179.  50 
159.  75 
214.  50 

149.  75 
179.  75 
204.  50 

229.50 
244.50 

249.  50 
274.  50 
289.50 

Model 

Cubic 
feet 

Price 

DAB          

3.1 
4.1 
4.1 
5.1 
5.1 
5.1 

6.0 
6.2 
6.2 

6.2 
6.2 

8.2 

SV3 

3.0 
4.0 

6.1 

5.0 
5.0 
6.0 
6.0 

6.0 
6.0 
6.0 
6.0 
6.0 
8.0 
8.0 
8.0 
8.0 

$119.50 

DA4 

SV4 

119.50 

Masters 

Master  5 

149.  50 

Specials 

Cold  Wall  Master  5 

Cold  Walls 

169.  50 

De  Lux 

174.50 

SVS6 

114.75 

Super  Value  6 

Super  Value  6 

129.50 

Special  6       .  ._  . 

Master  6 

Master  6 

159.50 

De  I,ux  6 

189.  50 

Cold  Wall  Master 

184.  50 

Cold  Wall 

Cold  Wall 

214.60 

Cold  Wall  (porcelain) 

Cold  Wall  (porcelain)..- 

Super  Value 

Masters 

Cold  Wall        ... 

239.  50 

Masters 

169.  50 
199.  50 

Cold  Wall 

8.0 
8.1 

254.50 

Cold  Wall  (porcelain) 

Cold  Wall  (porcelain).. 

279.  50 

GENERAL  ELECTRIC 

JB3 

3.2 
4.0 
5.0 
6.0 

6.0 

6.0 

8.25 

5.0 

6.1 

8.24 

6.1 

$119.75 
146.  50 
175.00 
192.00 

191.00 
218.00 
260.00 
217.00 
238.00 
283.00 
1.'9.  90 

JB4 

4.0 

5.0 

6.0 

3.0 

5.0 

6.0 

8.25 

5.0 

6.1 

8.24 

12.0 
16.0 
6.0 
3.0 
6.0 
8.0 

JB4 

$129.  75 

JB5 

JBS 

169.  75 

JB6 

JB6 

179.  75 

B3 

119.76 

B5 

B5 

197.  75 

B6 

B6 

B8 

214.  75 

B8. 

259.  75 

PB5 

PBS 

219.  50 

PB6 

PB6  .                 

239.50 

PBS 

PBS 

279.  50 

SP6 

PB12 

453.00 

PB16 

557. 00 

LB6B 

114.75 

LB3 

LB6 

119.76 
139.  75 

LBS 

179.  75 

It  is  highly  probable  thai  this  reduction  in  prices  contributed 
materially  to  the  sharp  expansion  in  sales  which  was  recorded  during 
the  early  months  of  1940.  Sales  of  electric  refrigerators  during  the 
first  quarter  of  1940  totaled  814,000  boxes,  compared  with  611,000 
for  the  same  period  in  1939;  an  increase  of  33  percent.  According 
to  the  New  York  Journal  of  Commerce  of  May  10,  1 940 — 

While  manufacturers'  shipments  of  refrigerators  are  not  holding  at  the  high 
level  of  the  first  quarter,  sales  to  dealers  for  the  first  half  of  the  year  will  show 
about  a  30-percent  rise  over  last. 

These  figures  seem  to  illustrate  clearly  the  possibility  of  expanding 
sales  by  reducing  prices  substantially.  It  is  still  too  early,  however, 
to  determine  the  extent  to  which  these  price  reductions  represent  a 
lasting  change  in  industry  policy,  rather  than  a  temporary  price  war. 

One  important  question  bearing  upon  the  interpretation  of  sales 
policy  is  the  extent  to  which  manufacturers  and  dealers  actually  try  to 
promote  the  sale  of  the  stripped  models  upon  which  the  major  reduc- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


157 


tions  have  been  announced,  or  alternatively  use  them  as  leaders  and 
attempt  to  divert  consumers  to  higher-priced  models  upon  which  the 
reductions  have  been  much  less  drastic.  There  is  evidence  that  at 
least  some  manufacturers  are  adopting  the  latter  rather  than  the 
former  policy.  For  example,  according  to  the  New  York  Journal  of 
Commerce — 

Favorable  consumer  response  to  the  new  low-priced  "stripped  refrigerators" 
caused  dealers  to  increase  orders  sharply.  Major  manufacturers  are  finding  it 
necessary  to  ration  deliveries  of  these  models,  to  discourage  dealers  from  promoting 
their  sale  at  the  expense  of  the  regular,  higher-price  lines.^" 

The  Air  Conditioning  and  Refrigeration  News  on  March  20,  1940, 
makes  this  significant  comment: 

An  interesting  phenomenon  is  the  "inability"  of  manufacturers  to  make  ship- 
ments of  the  lowest-priced  boxes.  Hundreds  of  dealers  are  reporting  to  prospects 
that  they  are  temporarily  "sold  out"  of  the  rock-bottom  jobs.  Shipments  are 
exceedingly  slow  in  arriving  from  the  factories.  This  fact  forces  them  to  "sell  up" 
to  the  higher-priced  boxes. 

The  same  trade  publication  on  March  27,  1940,  carried  the  following 
advertisement  by  the  Nash-Kelvinator  Corporation  addressed  to  its 
dealers,  in  which  the  policy  of  selling  higher-priced  models  wherever 
possible  was  strongly  advocated : 

Yes;  the  evidence  is  pouring  in — and  it  proves  the  soundness  of  Kelvinator's 
1940  program.  Look  at  the  chart  showing  the  percentage  of  Kelvinator's  sales 
by  models  and  prices,  and  then  compare  these  facts  with  your  own  sales.  The 
evidence  shows  clearly  that  Kelvinator  dealers  are  selling  higher-priced  mer- 
chandise. 

Those  who  sell  Kelvinator  have  more  than  a  selling  plan  *  *  *  they  have 
a  working  selling  plan.  And  it  is  working  because  it  was  carefully  planned  months 
ago  with  logical  and  easy-to-sell  step-ups  between  models.  There  are  low-priced 
models  for  the  vast  low-income  market  *  *  *  and  beautiful,  full-featured 
models  (including  the  new  "Moist-Master"  controlled  humidity  system)  specifi- 
cally designed  to  get  the  rapidly  growing  replacement  business.  Throughout 
Kelvinator's  line  of  sixes  and  eights  the  salesman  can  step  up  sales  because  plus 
features  in  each  step  offer  visible  and  provable  added  value  to  the  customer. 

79.8  percent  of  the  Kelvinator'  volume  is  in  refrigerators  with  the  greatest 
margin,  the  greatest  gross  dollar  sale.  The  average  unit  sales  price  is  better 
than  $160.« 

According  to  this  advertisement,  field  reports  received  by  the 
company  up  to  March  19  showed  that  actual  sales  of  the  various 
models  were  in  the  following  ratio : 


Price 

Model 

Percent 

Price 

Model 

Percent 

$114.75 

CSX-6 

SS-6 

S-6 

HS-6 

R-6 

6.4 
13.8 
30.3 
13.5 
12.5 

$179.95 

S-8 
HD-« 

R-8 
HD-8 

7.3 

$124.95 

$209.95    

8.1 

$139.95..  . 

$209.95.. 

4.1 

$169.95. 

$239.95 

4.0 

$179.95.. 

«  New  York  Journal  of  Commerce,  May  10, 1940. 

<i  Ad  rertisements  addressed  by  other  manufacturers  to  their  dealers  are  of  the  same  general  tenor.  For 
example — 

"Dealers— this  is  the  type  of  Norge  that  Mrs.  America  is  buying,  not  a  promotion  model  but  a  big 
de  luxe  model  that  carries  a  big,  full-sized  profit— the  kind  of  profit  you  need  and  must  have  to  stay  in  busi- 
ness. 

•  ••»••" 

"Of  course,  Norge  makes  low-priced  models,  too,  spectacular  promotion  models  and  full-profit  volume 
models,  all  useful  in  selling  the  whole  market— and  in  helping  you  to  'sell  up'  into  the  big  profit  figures." 
(Norge  advertisement,  Air  Conditioning  and  Refrigeration  News,  April  10,  p.  17.) 

"Here's  the  best  'step  up'  of  the  industry;  18  models.    $10  and  $20  steps— each  logical  and  easy  to  sell. 

"Shelvadors  sell  at  $99.95  to  $249.95  with  models  designed  for  easy  sales  steps  all  the  way  up.  You  can 
instantly  fit  any  family  need  and  pocketbook.  There's  no  high  jump  into  long  profit  models."  (Crosley 
advertisement,  Air  Conditioning  and  Refrigeration  News,  April  17,  p.  3.) 


25g  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  relatively  low  proportion  which  sales  of  the  stripped  model  bear 
to  total  sales,  according  to  this  advertisement,  is  striking  and  suggests 
that  dealers  are  cooperating  fully  in  this  "step  up"  program.  In  fact, 
one  dealer  reports  proudly  that  he  has  not  sold  a  single  stripped  model 
a,ll  season: 

More  refrigerator  sales  during  the  first  4  months  of  this  year  than  in  all  of  1 939, 
and  not  a  "special"  among  them — that's  the  record  of  Roy  L.  Eidman,  Kelvinator 
dealer. 

Mr.  Eidman  has  one  of  the  $114  models  on  his  sales  fioon — the  same  one  he 
"started  the  season  with.  But  it's  never  been  anywhere,  because  Mr.  Eidman 
and  his  four  salesmen  (two  full-time,  two  part-time)  have  worked  the  "step-up" 
plan  with  considerable  pleasure — and  profit. 

Most  of  the  company's  1940  sales  have  been  in  the  $140  range,  but  a  substantial 
nimiber  have  been  made  above  that  class,  Mr.  Eidman  said. 

******* 

Prospects  can  readily  see  the  extra  dollars'  worth  in  the  more  expensive  models, 
he  finds,  and  so  the  process  of  working  them  up  from  the  leader  models  hasn't 
been  at  all  tough.  In  general,  his  sales  method  is  to  show  the  prospect  the  model 
he  comes  in  and  asks  about — and  start  the  selling-up  tactics  from  that  point 
(Air  Conditioning  and  Refrigeration  News,  July  24,  1940,  p.  2). 

Another  dealer  in  describing  his  efforts  to  avoid  sales  of  the  less 
expensive  refrigerators  voices  a  somewhat  different  reaction: 

Manufacturers  may  be  hearing  songs  of  praise  in  many  quarters  for  dropping 
refrigerator  prices  this  year,  but  one  dealership  they'll  never  hear  from  in  this  vein 
is  General  Radio  &  Electric,  Westiughouse  retailer,  if  Clifford  Biggs,  one  of  the 
two  owners  of  the  place,  has  any  say-so  about  it. 

As  far  as  he's  concerned,  about  all  the  "specials"  have  accomplished  is  to  make 
higher-priced  models  harder  to  sell. 

"They  wouldn't  have  had  to  cut  the  prices  this  year  to  help  my  business,"  Mr. 
Biggs  said.  "If  people  want  good  refrigeration,  they're  willing  to  pay  for  it. 
We  sold  plenty  of  high-priced  models  when  the  mail-order  houses  were  'way  under 
us,  and  I  believe  we  could  have  kept  right  on  doing  it. 

"We'U  work  almost  as  hard  trying  not  to  sell  a  'special'  as  we  do  in  trying  to  sell 
a  de  luxe  model.  There's  no  money  in  specials,  so  we've  kept  away  from  them. 
Right  now  one  of  our  best  models  is  the  $160  job"  (Air  Conditioning  and  Refrigera- 
tion News,  July  24,  1940,  p.  2). 

It  seems  obvious  that  the  extent  to  which  decreases  in  price  will 
result  in  savings  to  the  consumer  and  in  expansion  of  sales  may  be 
largely  determined  by  the  popularity  and  acceptance  of  the  "stripped" 
leader.  If,  however,  the  bulk  of  the  sales  continue  to  go  to  other 
models,  the  net  savings  to  the  consumer  will  be  much  more  limited. 
Phis  may  also  mean  that  the  stimulation  of  sales  will  be  less  substantial 
and  less  lasting. 

Nevertheless,  it  is  evident  that  refrigerator  manufacturers  are  in 
the  process  of  recasting  their  sales  policies  to  meet  changing  conditions. 
Problems  such  as  the  relative  emphasis  upon  the  stripped  model, 
important  as  they  are,  may  well  solve  themselves  if  consumer  demand 
for  these  cheaper  lines  proves  to  be  sufficiently  insistent.  The  im- 
portant point  is  that  prices,  which  had  been  stable  between  1932  and 
1939,  are  again  in  the  process  of  reduction,  a  trend  which  may  well 
result  ultimately  in  a  sustained  higher  level  of  sales. 

THE    ROLE    OF    GOVERNMENT 

The  solution  of  the  market  problems  confronting  these  industries 
is  at  present  being  evolved  by  the  business  concerns  affected — either 
gradually  by  day-to-day  decisions  or  as  a  more  conscious  industry 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  l^Q 

policy.  Directly,  Government  has  not  taken  any  steps  to  influence 
these  decisions  of  business  policy.  In  the  present  organization  of 
the  industry  it  seems  evident  that  little  could  be  accomplished  through 
regulatory  action.  However,  certain  programs  undertaken  by 
Government  have  had  important  effects  upon  these  industries  and 
afford  an  illustration  of  the  manner  in  which  Government  action 
can  influence  industrial  markets. 

An  important  factor  in  the  market  for  these  products  has  been  the 
programs  which  are  focused  primarily  on  rendering  electric  power 
more  widely  and  cheaply  available.  The  regional  program  of  the 
Tennessee  Valley  Authority  and  the  work  done  by  the  Rural  Electri- 
fication Administration  to  encourage  the  extension  of  power  lines  into 
rural  areas  are  principal  examples.  By  thus  increasing  the  availability 
of  power,  these  activities  have  created  new  markets  and  increased  the 
number  of  potential  users  of  electrical  household  equipment. 

In  addition,  the  Federal  Government  has  acted  directly  to  stimulate 
the  sales  of  certain  kinds  of  equipment  to  families  in  low-income 
groups.  The  Federal  Housing  Administration,  for  example,  w^as 
authorized  from  June  1934  to  April  1937  to  insure  modernization  loans 
made  by  private  lending  institutions  for  the  purpose  of  repairing, 
modernizing,  or  improving  homes  and  other  properties.  Through 
May  1937,  Federal  Housing  Administration  had  insured  loans  of 
$2,000  and  less  for  single  and  multiple  family  residences  totaling 
$392,000,000.^^  There  is  no  information  available  to  indicate  what 
proportion  of  such  loans  was  for  electrical  household  equipment. 
However,  repossessions  were  high  and  later  regulations  excluded 
household  equipment  after  April  1,  1936. 

Another  important  step  in  the  direction  of  market  stimulation  was 
the  creation  of  the  Electric  Farm  and  Home  Authority,  which  was 
organized  to  finance  the  retail  purchase  of  electric  household  and  farm 
appliances  of  various  kinds.  The  Authority  originally  confined  its 
activities  to  electric  refrigerators,  water  heaters,  and  ranges;  the  list 
has  since  been  increased  to  19  kinds  of  equipment. 

In  its  activities  the  Authority  functions  in  cooperation  with  retaU 
dealers  and  privately  and  publicly  owned  utilities.  Prospective  pur- 
chasers whose  credit  is  found  acceptable  contract  directly  with  the 
dealer  for  the  purchase  of  equipment.  The  latter,  in  turn,  endorses 
the  contract  of  sale  and  receives  the  amount  of  the  unpaid  balance 
from  the  Electric  Farm  and  Home  Authority.  The  purchaser  pays 
monthly  installments  to  the  utility  which  provides  service,  and  these 
payments  are  transferred  to  Electric  Farm  and  Home  Authority. 

When  the  Authority  was  first  established,  5  years  ago,  its  activities 
were  confined  to  the  States  in  the  Tennessee  Valley  region.  During 
the  past  three  and  one-liplf  years,  however,  the  plan  has  been  extended 
to  many  other  areas  in  a  total  of  33  States,  where  the  rates  for  domestic 
power  consumption  are  considered  to  be  sufficiently  low  to  justify  the 
use  of  electrical  appliances  by  families  with  restricted  incomes. 

Since  the  purpose  of  the  Electric  Farm  and  Home  Authority  was  to 
render  the  use  of  these  labor  saving  devices  available  to  low-income 
groups,  efforts  were  made  to  reduce  the  original  price  of  appliances 
eligible  for  financing.  When  the  Authority  started  operations,  it  was 
believed  that  much  of  the  equipment  on  the  market  was  too  expensive 

"  Federal  Housing  Administration  Annual  Report  for  Year  Ending  December  31, 1937. 


160 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


for  families  which  it  was  desired  to  benefit.  Consequently,  an  effort 
was  made  to  induce  manufacturers  to  offer  a  cheaper  product.  The 
Authority  drew  up  specifications  for  a  4-foot  refrigerator  designed  to 
retail  at  $79  to  $89  in  the  Tennessee  Valley  area.  Later  a  2-cubic  foot, 
chest  model  refrigerator  with  a  lift  top  was  substituted  to  retail  at 
the  same  price.  At  first  manufacturers  cooperated,  generally,  in  this 
program  of  price  reduction.  However,  manufacturing  costs  increased 
in  the  latter  part  of  1934  and  1935,  partly  due  to  the  influence  of 
N.  R.  A.  code  agreements.  Since  that  period,  the  Authority  has 
made  no  direct  attempt  to  influence  the  prices  of  equipment.  Only 
certain  designated  makes  are  eligible  for  financing,  and  in  selecting 
these  makes  the  Authority  considers  "such  factors  as  the  financial 
responsibility  and  reputation  of  the  applicant^  quality  and  design  of 
equipment,  and  prices."  *^ 

Through  June  30,  1939,  the  Electric  Home  and  Farm  Authority 
had  accepted  151,000  financing  contracts. 

The  Rural  Electrification  Administration,  in  addition  to  its  primary 
function  of  rendering  electrical  power  available  to  the  farm  population, 
also  promotes  the  sale  of  electrical  appliances  by  assisting  in  the 
financing  of  water  pumps  and  heaters. 

The  Rural  Electrification  Administration  has  conducted  two  surveys 
designed  to  measure  the  extent  of  use  of  electrical  appliances  eligible 
for  Electric  Home  and  Farm  Authority  or  Rural  Electrification 
Administration  financing  in  Rural  Electrification  Administration 
territory.  They  indicate  a  very  widespread  immediate  purchase  of 
certain  equipment,  such  as  electric  irons  and  radios,  followed  closely 
by  washing  machines,  refrigerators,  and  toasters." 

To  a  considerable  extent  the  purchases  reflected  in  these  surveys 
represent  net  additions  to  the  electrical  appliance  markets  which 
might  have  been  difficult  to  achieve  without  the  aid  of  Government. 


Ten  leading 

appliances  in  each  of  two  studies 

July  1938  survey  (6.0  months'  service  experience) 

January  1938  survey  (8.4  months'  service  experience) 

Item 

Percent  of 

families 
purchasing 

Item 

Percent  of 

families 
purchasing 

Hand  iron 

83 
80 
56 
30 
25 
19 
17 
15 
11 
10 
3 

Radio                       

86 

Radio 

Hand  iron -. 

81 

Wtishing  machine    ... 

Washing  machine                           . 

47 

Refrigerator 

Refrigerator                            .  .  . 

26 

Toaster 

24 

Vacuum  cleaner 

Water  pump 

17 

Water  pump 

Vacuum  cleaner 

16 

Hot  plate 

12 

Motor,  up  to  1  horsepower 

Motor,  up  to  1  horsepower 

9 

Cream  separator 

Poultry  lighting                   .        ... 

9 

No  appliances .^ 

3 

Source:  Rural  Electrification  News,  January  1939. 


"  Electric  Farm  and  Home  Authority,  Annual  Report  forthe  Fiscal  Year  Ending  June  30,  1938. 
**  Purchases  of  electrical  appliances  by  families  participating  in  Rural  Electrification  Administration 
programs. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  JgJ 

CONCLUSIONS 

It  is  clear  that  for  some  of  these  electrical-appliance  industries  at 
least,  the  early  period  of  easy  and  rapid  growth  has  reached,  or  is  about 
to  reach,  an  end.  The  sales  policies  which  were  well  adapted  to  intro- 
duce these  commodities  to  the  more  prosperous  sectors  of  the  popula- 
tion may  be  on  the  verge  of  outliving  their  usefulness.  Certainly  as 
the  market  for  original  sales  among  this  group  of  consumers  dwindles, 
it  becomes  imperative  that  these  policies  be  seriously  re-examined. 
Certain  governmental  activities  designed  to  stimulate  sales  among  the 
lower-income  groups  may  confer  limited  benefits,  but  it  seems  clear 
that  the  basic  solution  must  come  from  the  industries  themselves. 

Two  major  fields  for  future  expansion  have  been  suggested.  The 
first  is  the  potential  market  among  families  who  have  not  been  able 
to  afford  to  purchase  these  products  at  their  present  levels  of  prices. 
The  second  is  the  stimulation  of  the  replacement  market,  by  increasing 
the  incentive  and  reducing  the  cost  of  exchanging  old  equipment  for 
new. 

In  both  of  these  fields  price  is  of  paramount  concern.  The  question 
has  been  raised  as  to  whether  it  is  feasible  for  these  industries  to  re- 
sume the  policy  of  aggressive  price  reductions  which  characterized 
their  earlier  history.  It  has  been  shown,  for  example,  that  during 
recent  years  sales  strategy  has  shifted  from  price  appeal  to  nonprice 
channels ;  it  has  been  suggested  that  this  may  have  resulted  in  increas- 
ing rather  than  reducing  costs  and  prices.  Is  there  any  prospect  of 
reversing  this  trend?  Is  there  any  hope  of  expanding  the  market 
sufficiently  by  further  price  reductions  to  achieve  manufacturing 
economies  adequate  to  make  the  venture  profitable? 

Or  has  the  limit  of  important  technological  advances  been  reached, 
at  least  as  far  as  manufacturing  economy  is  concerned?  Undoubtedly 
these  are  questions  with  which  the  members  of  these  industries  are 
seriously  concerned.  The  recent  experience  of  the  refrigerator  indus- 
try suggests  that  there  may  be  a  very  real  possibility  of  reducing  prices 
sufficiently  to  tap  new  markets. 

A  basic  problem  is  the  cost  of  distribution.  It  has  been  shown  that 
this  cost  ^v.  :u  .(S  for  approximately  one-half  of  tlio  retail  price.  It 
constitute^  an  imposing  obstacle  both  to  price  reductions  for  new 
equipment  .iii  to  attractive  allowances  for  used  equipment  offered 
in  trade,  '^hcre  seems  to  be  some  evidence  that  thli  jost  can  be 
reduced  through  the  use  of  mass-distribution  me. hot i?  Whether 
similar  economies  can  be  achieved  through  ordinary  Iistrii  ative  chan- 
nels is  an  important  question.  Apparently  some  manii^  cturers  fear 
that  reductioi.  in  distributive  margins  would  result  in  tl  3  loss  of  cer- 
tain retail  out  its.  On  the  other  hand,  this  might  not  necessarily  be 
equivalent  to  ..  loss  of  sales.  It  is  conceivable  that  a  sTialler  number 
of  outlets,  operating  at  narrower  mark-ups  and  consequently  lower 
prices,  with  a  larger  volume  of  sales  through  each  outlr^t,  might  pro- 
vide a  more  efficient  and  more  economical  method  of  disiibution  than 
the  one  at  present  in  use. 


162 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Finally,  there  are  problems  which  the  industries  seem  now  to  be 
attacking,  such  as  the  disposition  and  reconditioning  of  used  models 
accepted  in  trade.  Here  there  is  little  reason  for  doubting  that  im- 
portant advances  in  technique  will  soon  be  achieved. 

In  short,  the  saturation  of  a  substantial  segment  of  the  original 
markets  does  not  necessarily  mark  the  end  of  the  period  of  expansion 
for  these  industries  or  for  others  in  like  position.  It  does,  however, 
make  imperative  a  searching  re-examination  of  sales  policies  generally 
and  of  price  policies  in  particular,  and  an  appropriate  revision  of 
these  policies  to  cope  with  the  changing  character  of  the  market. 

The  importance  of  the  industries  which  have  been  described  in  the 
foregoing  pages  does  not  lie  primarily  in  their  size  nor  even  in  the 
relationship  which  they  bear  to  other  segments  of  the  economy.  It 
consists  rather  in  the  fact  that  the  problems  with  which  they  are 
currently  confronted  typify  a  pattern  of  much  more  general  application. 
All  industries  producing  consumers'  durable  goods  must,  at  some 
stage  in  their  individual  histories,  face  a  transition  from  a  market 
composed  largely  of  original  sales  to  one  in  which  replacements  pre- 
dominate. It  may  be  noted  in  passing  that  the  decline  in  the  rate 
of  population  growth,  which  has  been  stressed  by  witnesses  before 
the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,*^  aggravates  the 
change  by  narrowing  the  possibility  of  original  sales  to  the  successive 
increments  of  population. 

Such  transitions  in  the  character  of  the  market  are  inevitable  for 
industries  of  this  kind.  The  manner  in  which  the  firms  involved 
adjust  their  marketing  techniques  and  price  policies  to  changed  con- 
ditions will  largely  determine  the  subsequent  growth  of  these  indus- 
tries and  the  opportunities  which  they  will  offer  for  employment  and 
investment. 


Table 

21.^ — List  prices  of  ele 

dric  ref 

rigerators  1938,  principal  companies  ' 

Size,  cubic 
feet 

Frigid- 
aire 

General 
Elec- 
tric 

Westing- 
house 

Kelvin- 
ator 

Crosley 

Leon- 
ard 

Norge 

Stewart 
Warner 

Uni- 
versal 
Cooler 

Cold- 
spot 

3.0  to  3.9: 
Size 

3.1 

D3 

$119.50 

4.1 

N4-3S 
$144. 50 

5.1 

Sp.  5-38 

$164. 50 

6.1 

Sp.  6-38 

$184.  75 

7.2 
Sp.  7-38 
$204.  75 

8.25 
M8-38 
$264. 50 

4 
B^ 

$144.  50 

5 
JB-5 

$164.95 

6.1 
JB-6 

$184. 75 

7.1 
JB-7 

$204. 75 

8.1 

B-8 

$204.50 

3.2 

nDS-32 

$119.50 

4.2 
HDS-J2 

$144.  50 

5.2 
HS-52 

$169.  50 

6.2 
HS-62 
$189.  50 

7.2 
HS-72 
$209.  50 

3.16 

K3-38 

$118.  95 

4.15 

£4-38 

$142. 95 

5.16 
KS5-38 
$162. 95 

6.13 
KS6-38 
$182. 95 

7.19 
KS7-38 
$202.95 

3.16 
KB5-31 
$117. 50 

4.3 
KB5-43 

$142.  50 

6.07 
KB5-50 
$162. 50 

6.0 
.KB5-«0 
$182. 50 

7.1 
KB5-71 
$202.00 

3.14 

L3-38 

$118.95 

4.1 

L4-38 

$142.95 

5.12 
LS5-38 
$162.95 

6.09 
LS6-38 
$182. 95 

7.3 
LS7-38 
$202.  95 

3.12 

R32-8 

$117.50 

4.14 

R41-8 

$142. 50 

5.15 

S52-8 

$162.  50 

6.15 

S62-8 

$182.  50 

7.14 
S71-B 
$202.50 

8.11 

R81-8 

$259. 50 

Model 

Price 

4.0  to  4.9: 

Size 

4.5 

458 

$144.  75 

5.64 

550 

$164.  75 

6.3 

770 
$179.  75 

4.2 

Model 

3804 

Price 

$114.50 

5.0  to  5.9: 

Size 

Model 

Price 

6.0  to  6.9: 

Size 

Model.... 

Price 

7.0  to  7.9: 

Size_ 

Model 

Price 

8.0  to  8.9: 

Size 

5.25 
AD-538 
$164. 95 

6.51 
AD-C5S 
$184.95 

7.45 
AD-758 
$204. 95 

6.3 

3816 

$169.  50 

8.6 

Model 

3838 

Price 

$179. 50 

>  Prices  are  on  lowest  price  comparable  model  in  each  size  group. 

Source:  Air  Conditioning  and  Refrigeration  News,  Business  News  Publishing  Co.,  Mar.  9,  1938. 

«  See  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  Hearings,  Part  9,  pp.  3504-350& 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Table  22. — Percent  of  concertration,  1937 


163 


Item 

Production  of 
first    four 
companies 

Percent 

of 

total 

Total  pro- 
duction 

Number 
of  com- 
panies 

ELECTKIC  REFRIGERATORS,  DOMESTIC 

Capacity  under  6  cubic  feet: 

Number .  . 

754, 130 
$58, 464,  364 

728,  660 
$73,  739, 375 

(■) 
$2,  406, 123 

717, 900 
$28,  515,  327 

(1) 
$22,  986,  563 

69 
69 

74 

77 

0) 
77 

49 
53 

(0 
70 

1,093,026 
$84,  458, 077 

991,  022 
$95, 985, 895 

(') 
$3, 130, 046 

1, 478,  480 
$53,  759,  751 

1, 190,  782 
$33, 016, 817 

Value--- 

21 

Capacity  6  to  under  10  cubic  feet: 

Number            .                     -  .      - 

Value      .-  - 

25 

Capacity  10  cubic  feet  and  over  (including  those  not  re- 
ported by  size): 
Number ^ 

Value 

14 

WASHING   MACHINES,  HOUSEHOLD  USE   aNCLUDING   APART- 
MENT SIZE) 

Number    - - .- 

Value - 

32 

VACUUM  CLEANERS,  FLOOR 

Number 

Value 

29 

>  Data  not  available. 

Source:  Bureau  of  the  Census,  Department  of  Commerce. 

Table  23. — Cash  value  on  trade-ins 
[Cash  value  as  percent  of  list  price,  delivered  '] 


Year 

Electric  refrigerators 

Automobiles 

7-foot  > 

6-foot  3 

5-foot  > 

4-foot  » 

Coach  < 

Coach  • 

1933..- - 

Percent 
10.0 
11.0 
21.0 
23.0 
32.0 

Percent 
13.8 
17.9 
22.2 
24.2 
32.4 

Percent 
10.3 
16.6 
21.3 
24.7 
31.6 

Percent 
16.6 
18.5 
24.1 
25.5 
34.8 

Percent 
15.1 
22.2 
30.6 
39.0 
52.6 
63.1 

Percent 
11  7 

1934 , 

18  6 

1935-. 

29  3 

1936 

39  5 

1937 

49  8 

1938 

63.3 

'  Refrigerators:  Manufacturers'  suggested  retail  delivered  price;  northeast  zone.     Automobiles:  E.sti- 
mated  delivered  retail  price,  Washington,  D.  C. 
'  Company  A. 
'  Company  B. 
<  Company  C, 
•  Company  D. 

Source  (Refrigerators):  The  National  Market  Index,  published  by  the  National  Refrigrator  Index 
Publishing  Co.,  Inc.  (Automobiles):  Blue  Book,  Executives'  Edition,  published  by  the  National  Used 
Car  Market  Report,  Inc. 


164 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  24. — Average  expenditxires  by  families  of  employed  wage  earners  and  clerical 

workers  by  economic  level  ' 


■5 

Electric  re- 

Washing 

Vacuum 

Electric 
stoves  and 
hot  plates 

S>. 

frigerators 

machines 

cleaners 

£g 

i 

.2 

3 

.2 

^ 

.2 

^ 

_» 

5^ 

Economic  level— family  spending 

fen, 

B  tD 

•3°iL 

B  tB 

'St. 

B  bc 

"5? 

§Sf 

'3 1!. 

per  expenditure  unit  per  year 

S-- 

.■a 

i§ 

a>? 

•oS 

n>> 

•o'i 

pi? 

o  3 

a^ 

a  ^ 

g 

o-B 

o-a 

Q.S 

aa 

X  3 

<uX3 

^ 

la 

bo  2 
OS  O. 

a  Q. 

sa 

a  o. 

as 

> 

S 
i-t 

fe 

> 

S 

u 
U 

S 

> 

8 

> 

■< 

■< 

P4 

< 

PM 

< 

Ph 

< 

(U 

< 

All  families 

3.32 

$1,  538 

6.0 

$9.77 

5.9 

$3.70 

4.6 

$1.97 

0.7 

$0.38 

Under  $200                    .    ..           

5.96 
4.79 

1,021 
1,219 

1.1 
1.4 

1.98 
2.30 

3.4 

5.2 

2.43 
3.00 

$200  and  under  $300 

1.9 

,91 

.2 

.04 

$300  and  under  $400 -- 

3.84 

1,352 

2.9 

4.90 

6.3 

3.74 

2.5 

1.03 

.6 

.24 

$400  and  under  $500 -- 

3.30 
2.94 

1,487 
1,606 

6.0 
6.9 

9.31 
11.34 

6.6 
6.0 

4.11 
3.81 

4.5 
60 

2.02 
2.63 

.6 
.6 

.29 

$500  and  under  $600 

.40 

$600  and  under  $700 _ 

2.62 

1.694 

8.6 

13.69 

,5.7 

3.88 

,5  3 

2.12 

1  ?. 

.48 

$700  and  under  $800 

1.99 

1,787 

8.6 

14.61 

4.9 

3.32 

5.6 

2.32 

1.0 

.51 

$800  and  under  $900     

2.27 
2.20 

1,868 
1,984 

11.1 

11.7 

19.95 
17.65 

5.2 
6.8 

3.04 
5.31 

8.5 
3.7 

3.88 
1.21 

1.8 
.6 

.77 

$900  and  under  $1,000        

.64 

$1,000  and  under  $1,100 

2.23 

2,102 

12.1 

21.57 

5.8 

3.93 

10.6 

5.19 

2.2 

2.00 

$1,100  and  under  $1,200...              

2.17 

2,255 

12.1 

20.42 

7.8 

4.97 

9.1 

6.02 

.5 

.51 

$1,200  and  over      ..  .     .          

1.94 

2,395 

12.9 

20.13 

3.9 

2.67 

15.1 

6.62 

3.1 

2.39 

'  Economic  level  is  determined  by  the  amount  spent  per  expenditure  unit,  a  measure  which  takes  into 
account  total  family  expenditure  and  family  size  and  composition.  An  e.xplanation  of  the  method  of  com- 
puting this  measure  was  given  in  the  Monthly  Labor  Review  for  March  1936  (pp.  558-559). 

2  Average  for  families  in  42  large  cities  from  unpublished  data  o'  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  based  on 
total  number  of  families  in  group,  not  on  families  purchasing. 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  "Study  of  Money  Disbursements  of  Wage  Earners  and  Clerical 
Workers." 


APPENDIX  I  ' 
MEASURES  OF  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 

PURPOSE 

In  the  course  of  the  discussion  of  price  flexibility  contained  in 
chapter  II  of  this  report,  reference  was  made  to  the  various  ways  in 
which  price  sensitivity  may  be  measured.     (See  ch.  II,  pp.  27-31.) 

A  distinction  was  drawn  at  the  outset  between  criteria  designed  to 
measure  the  responsiveness  of  prices  to  the  specific  economic  forces 
affecting  their  markets,  and  criteria  based  solely  upon  the  observed 
behavior  of  prices.  It  was  pointed  out  that,  although  criteria  of  the 
former  kind  were  in  some  ways  more  significant,  practical  considera- 
tions made  it  necessary  to  use  behavioristic  measures  at  the  present 
time. 

It  is  the  purpose  of  this  appendix  to  present  data  relating  to  the 
flexibility  of  784  ^  individual  price  series  included  in  the  Bureau  of 
Labor  Statistics  weighted  wholesale  price  index,  as  measured  by  vari- 
ous aspects  of  their  behavior.  A  total  of  14  different  measures  is 
presented;  2  of  these  were  prepared  by  the  National  Resources  Com- 
mittee, 1 1  were  developed  in  the  course  of  the  present  study,  and  1  is 
based  upon  an  earlier  analysis  by  this  Bureau.  All  of  these  measures 
were  based  upon  the  behavior  of  these  price  series  subsequent  to 
January  1926.^ 

The  criteria  presented  are  designed  to  measure  three  general  aspects 
of  price  behavior:  (1)  The  frequency  of  price  change,  (2)  the  ampli- 
tude of  cychcal  price  movement,  (3)  the  timing  of  changes  in  price 
trends. 

Twelve  of  the  criteria  (A  to  L,  inclusive)  are  based  upon  some  one 
of  these  aspects  alone.  The  two  remaining  criteria  (M  and  N)  are 
designed  to  measure  the  combined  effect  of  frequency  and  amplitude 
of  change. 

In  computing  these  measures,  169  of  the  individual  price  series 
reported  by  the  Bureau  were  grouped  into  50  composites  in  conformity 
with  procedure  utilized  by  the  National  Resources  Committee.*  For 
example,  prices  are  published  by  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  for 
six  different  kinHs  of  wheat.  These  sLx  series  show  closely  parallel 
movements  and  may  therefore  be  satisfactorily  represented  by  a  single 
composite  series.     The  purpose  of  using  composites   was   to   avoid 

'  Appendix  I  was  prepared  by  Saul  Nelson  and  Walter  G.  Keim.  Joseph  W.  Lethco  assisted  In  pre- 
paring the  statistical  data. 

'  During  January  1938,  the  index  was  expanded  to  include  813  individual  series,  and  during  January  1940, 
it  was  enlarged  to  863  series,  but  data  for  the  additional  series  are  inadequate  to  permit  their  inclusion  in 
this  analysis. 

'  This  date  marks  the  point  at  which  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  wholesale-price  data  were  materially 
revised  and  many  new  series  added.  Measures  of  price  behavior  prior  to  1926  are  included  in  The  Behavior 
of  Prices,  by  Frederick  C.  Mills,  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research,  1927,  and  also  in  Prices  In  the 
Trade  Cycle,  by  Qerhardt  Tintner,  Vienna,  1935. 

*  The  Structure  of  the  American  Economy,  National  Resources  Committee,  pt.  I,  June  1939,  p.  186. 

165 


IQQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

imputing  excessive  weight  to  the  items  comprising  them  in  the  calcu- 
lations and  correlation  charts.  For  example,  the  retention  of  18 
individual  butter  series,  in  place  of  a  single  composite,  would  m  effect 
give  butter  a  weight  18  times  greater  than  that  for  other  products 
which  were  represented  by  single  series. 

The  criteria  of  flexibility  for  the  composites  were  derived  from  the 
criteria  for  their  individual  constituents.  In  the  case  of  measures  J, 
K,  and  L,  reflecting  the  timing  of  price  change,  the  criterion  for  the 
composite  is  the  median  of  the  measures  for  the  series  included.  In 
all  other  cases  the  arithmetic  mean  of  the  criteria  for  the  individual 
series  was  computed  to  obtain  the  corresponding  measure  of  flexibility 
for  the  composite.  In  this  way  the  tendency  of  composites  to  yield 
misleading  measures  (e.  g.,  composites  generally  show  a  greater  fre- 
quency of  change  than  any  of  their  components)  was  avoided. 

These  measures  are  presented  with  full  awareness  that  there  are 
inherent  inaccuracies  in  the  basic  data  for  this  purpose.  It  has  been 
pointed  out  repeatedly  that  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  wholesale- 
price  indexes  are  not  ideal  for  the  measurement  of  price  flexibility. 
Thus,  for  some  commodities,  price  changes  take  forms  such  as  rebates, 
concessions  in  terms  of  sale,  or  modifications  of  the  nature  of  the 
commodity  which  are  not  reflected  in  reported  price  data.  Allowance 
for  some  of  these  changes  may  later  be  made  possible  in  the  course  of 
the  Bureau's  program  of  revision  and  refinement  of  its  price  series. 
Other  difficulties,  such  as  changes  in  the  nature  of  the  commodity, 
may  prove  difficult  or  impossible  to  correct.  Nevertheless,  in  view 
of  the  current  interest  in  the  subject,  it  was  considered  desirable  to 
present  these  criteria  of  price  flexibility  on  the  basis  of  the  price  data 
now  available. 

THE  CRITERIA  UTILIZED 

A  description  of  the  specific  criteria  to  be  presented  follows: 

(1)  Criteria  based  upon  frequency  of  change. — 

A.  Number  of  monthly  changes  in  price,  1926  to  1933.  This  cri- 
terion was  first  presented  by  Gardiner  C.  Means  in  Industrial  Prices 
and  Their  Relative  Inflexibility.'^  It  has  been  somewhat  amplified 
and  revised  by  the  National  Resources  Committee  and  is  inc'  ided 
in  the  recent  report  of  the  Committee,  The  Structure  of  the  American 
Economy.^ 

B.  Number  of  montlily  changes  in  price,  January  1926  to  April 
1929.  This  criterion  is  designed  to  present  a  measure  of  frequency  of 
price  change  during  a  period  of  relatively  full  resource  utilization. 

(2)  Measures  based  upon  the  amplitude  of  cyclical  price  change. — • 

C.  The  amplitude  of  downswing  during  the  1929-33  recession,  as 
measured  by  the  percentage  of  decline  from  January  1929  to  Feb- 
ruary 1933.  The  bulk  of  these  data  were  presented  in  an  earlier 
publication  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.'^ 

D.  This  is  a  measure  of  the  amplitude  of  cyclical  upswing.  It  is 
based  upon  the  percentage  of  increase  from  the  depression  *  low  to 
the  1937  peak,  computed  as  a  percentage  of  the  former. 

>  S.  Doc.  n,  74th  Cong.,  1st  sess. 

•  The  Structure  of  the  American'Economy,  National  Resources  Committee,  Juno  1939,  pt.  I,  pp.  186-204. 

'  U.  S.  Department  of  Labor,  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics,  The  Trends  of  Wholesale  Prices,  June  1929 
to  1933  (mimeographed). 

'  For  purpo.ses  of  convenience  the  term  "depres.sion,"  if  not  otherwise  modified,  will  be  used  to  denote 
the  1929-33  downswing. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  lg7 

The  last  two  criteria  described  measured  downswing  and  upswing 
separately.  The  next  three  (E,  F,  and  G)  combine  elements  of  up- 
swing and  downswing.  Each  of  these  three  measures  is  based  upon 
a  comparison  of  the  depression  low  price  with  the  average  of  the  pre- 
depression  and  post-depression  peaks.  One  of  the  purposes  of  this 
technique  is  to  make  some  allowance  for  secular  trends  during  the 
period  1929-37.  For  example,  the  prices  of  such  commodities  as 
rayon  and  electric  refrigerators  experienced  a  broad  secular  down- 
trend during  most  of  this  period.  Consequently,  measures  based  ex- 
clusively either  upon  the  amplitude  of  downswing  or  upon  the  am- 
plitude of  upswing  are  misleading. 

E.  Criterion  E  was  developed  by  the  National  Resources  Committee 
and  is  included  in  The  Structure  of  the  American  Economy.'^  It  is 
based  upon  the  difference  in  index  points  between  the  1932  annual 
price  average  and  the  mean  of  the  1929  and  1937  annual  prices, 
expressed  on  the  basis  of  1929  equals  100. 

Criteria  F  and  G  may  be  distinguished  from  E  in  two  respects. 
In  the  first  place  they  are  based  upon  monthly  rather  than  average 
annual  data.  Consequently  they  reflect  the  extreme  peaks  and  lows 
somewhat  better,  but  on  the  other  hand  they  are  influenced  by  seasonal 
price  movements.  In  the  second  place,  the  difference  between  the 
depression  low  and  the  two  peaks  is  expressed  as  a  percentage  of  the, 
average  of  the  latter  rather  than  on  the  basis  of  1929  equals  100.  It 
is  considered  that  this  procedure  is  somewhat  better  adapted  to 
compensate  for  secular  influences, 

F.  Criterion  F  is  based  upon  the  difference  between  thfe  mean  of  the 
monthly  peaks  during  the  years  1929  and  1937,  and  the  low  month  of 
the  depression,  expressed  as  a  percentage  of  the  former. 

G.  Criterion  G  is  distinguished  from  F  merely  in  that  the  post- 
depression  peak  month  was  taken  during  the  period  between  January 
1936  and  March  1937,  inclusive,  instead  of  during  the  calendar  year 
1937.  This  was  designed  to  eliminate  the  influence  of  the  sharp  rises 
in  the  prices  of  certain  otherwise  insensitive  commodities  which  took 
place  during  the  latter  part  of  1937,  well  after  the  general  down  trend 
was  under  way. 

Criteria  H  and  I  are  similar  to  the  two  just  described,  in  that  they 
measure  the  relation  of  the  depression  low  to  the  predepression  and 
postdepression  peaks.  They  represent  two  alternative  devices  for 
minimizing  seasonal  influences. 

H.  This  criterion  is  based  upon  the  percentage  of  decrease  between 
the  average  of  the  1929  and  1937  annual  prices  and  the  1932  annual 
average  price,  expressed  as  a  percentage  of  the  former.  This  use'  of 
annual  averages  eliminates  seasonal  influences.  This  criterion  is 
similar  to  the  National  Resources  criterion  E,  except  that  the  decline 
is  expressed  as  a  percentage,  rather  than  in  index  points. 

I.  Measure  I  is  based  on  the  percentage  decline  between  the  average 
of  the  February  1929  and  February  1937  prices,  and  the  February 
1 933  price,  computed  as  a  percentage  of  the  former.  The  use  of  the 
the  same  mr  th  in  each  year  should  largely  eliminate  seasonal  varia- 
tion. The  month  of  February  was  selected  because  prices  during 
February  1933  were  close  to  the  depression  lows  and  prices  during 
February  1937  generally  approximated  the  recovery  highs. 

•  Op.  cU,  loc.  cit. 

24  7149 — 41— No.  1 1.3 


168  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(3)  Measures  based  upon  timing  of  price  change. — J.  This  criterion 
is  the  month  during  which  the  predepression  peak  was  reached,  based 
upon  the  period  January  1929  to  December  1931,  For  most  com- 
modities, of  couise,  the  peak  month  occurred  during  1929,  but  in  some 
cases  the  downtrend  started  much  later.  Some  commodities  showed 
no  decline  at  all  during  this  period. 

K.  Measure  K  is  the  month  durLug  which  the  depression  low  was 
reached.  The  period  included  is  from  January  1932  to  December 
1934. 

L.  Criterion  L  consists  of  the  month  during  which  the  postdepres- 
sion  peak  was  reached,  preceding  the  1937-38  downswing.  Data  are 
based  upon  the  period  January  1936  to  December  1938. 

(4)  Measures  combining  frequency  and  amplitude. — Criteria  M  and 
N  are  designed  to  yield  measures  reflecting  both  frequency  and  ampli- 
tude of  change  during  a  period  of  relatively  full  resource  utilization. 
Price  behavior  was  observed  during  the  period  between  January  1926 
and  AprU  1929,  inclusive.  For  each  price  series,  the  aggregate  change 
in  price  during  this  period,  regardless  of  sign,  was  totaled. 

M.  Criterion  M  is  obtained  by  dividing  the  aggregate  change  in 
price  during  the  period  January  1926  to  April  1929  (computed  as 
explained  above)  by  the  actual  number  of  price  changes  displayed 
during  that  period.  This  yields  a  measure  of  the  average  number  of 
points  by  which  each  price  index  changes  when  it  does  change;  i.  e., 
of  change  per  change. 

N.  From  the  aggregate  change  in  price  during  the  period  January 
1926  to  April  1929  was  subtracted  the  net  change  in  price  between 
the  beginning  and  end  of  this  period.  This  procedure  was  designed 
to  yield  a  measure  of  the  total  amount  of  price  movement  which  did 
not  result  in  an  ultimate  net  change  in  price.  It  may  be  considered 
to  constitute  a  rough  approximation  of  the  total  casual  and  seasonal 
variation  experienced  by  each  series  during  this  period. 

PRESENTATION    OF    THE    DATA 

Tables  25  and  26  present  the  flexibility  of  each  of  the  individual 
price  series  and  composites  as  measured  by  each  of  these  criteria. 

In  table  I  the  actual  measures  themselves  are  shown.  It  will  be 
noted  that  measures  are  omitted  for  some  of  the  series  for  some  of 
the  criteria.  The  character  of  the  data  made  this  necessary.  In 
some  cases  the  available  data  did  not  cover  a  sufficient  period  of  time 
to  permit  the  computation  of  certain  measures.  For  other  items 
criteria  A  and  E  were  not  available  in  the  tabulation  of  the  National 
Resources  Committee.  Moreover  a  considerable  number  of  com- 
modities showed  no  change  whatever  between  January  1926  and 
April  1929.  For  these  commodities  criterion  M — average  change  per 
change — could  obviously  not  be  computed. 

For  the  purposes  of  table  26  the  series  were  ranked  in  ten  groups, 
or  "deciles,"  on  the  basis  of  each  of  these  criteria.  Group  I  included 
those  commodities  which  displayed  least  flexibihty  as  judged  by  the 
measure  in  question,  and  group  X  included  those  commodities  which 
displayed  most  flexibility.  As  far  as  possible,  an  attempt  was  made 
to  include  the  same  number  of  commodities  in  each  group,  but  the 
character  of  the  data  precluded  uniformity  in  the  process.     In  two 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  169 

cases  deciles  had  to  be  combined.^"  Table  26  presents  the  results  of 
this  method  of  ranking;  it  shows  the  decile  into  which  each  series 
falls  as  judged  by  each  of  the  measures  used. 

RELATIONSHIPS    BETWEEN    THE    MEASURES    PRESENTED 

Since  these  criteria  measure  different  aspects  of  price  behavior,  it 
is  to  be  expected  that  the  relative  degree  of  flexibility  exhibited  by 
specific  commodity  prices  will  vary  with  the  measure  used.  On  the 
other  hand,  it  was  poLuted  out  in  chapter  II  (pp.  31-32)  that  under- 
lying differences  in  market  patterns  lead  to  the  existence  of  certain 
broad  relationships  between  different  phases  of  behavior;  as  for 
example  between  frequency  of  change  and  ampUtude  of  cyclical 
movement. 

In  order  to  facihtate  comparison  between  the  various  measures 
compiled,  a  series  of  18  tables  (tables  27  to  44  inclusive)  has  been 
prepared."  Each  of  these  tables  compares  the  decUe  ranking  of  all 
the  items  for  which  data  are  available  for  two  measures  of  flexibility. 
For  example,  table  27  compares  the  percentage  of  decline  from  June 
1929  to  February  1933  (criterion  C)  with  the  percentage  of  rise  from 
the  depression  low  to  the  peak  of  1927  (criterion  D).  Thus  this 
table  shows  that,  for  the  65  items  ranked  as  most  insensitive  under 
measure  C,  data  were  also  available  under  measure.  D;  that  31  of 
these  65  items  were  also  in  the  most  inflexible  group  under  the  latter 
measure,  16  in  the  next  most  rigid  group  (group  II)  five  in  group 
III,  five  in  group  IV,  etc.  Similarly  42  of  the  items  which  were 
classed  as  most  flexible  under  criterion  C  were  also  in  the  most  flexible 
group  under  criterion  D. 

These  tables  are  presented  in  the  following  order: 

Table  27  compares  depression  decline  (1929-33)  with  recovery 
(1933-37). 

Table  28  compares  the  timing  of  the  depression  downturn  (1929-31) 
with  that  of  the  initial  recovery  (1932-34), 

Table  29  compares  the  timing  of  the  depression  downturn  (1929-31) 
with  that  of  the  1936-38  recession. 

Table  30  compares  the  timing  of  the  initial  recovery  with  that  of 
the  1936-38  recession. 

Tables  31  to  34,  inclusive,  compare  frequency  of  change  with  amp- 
litude of  cyclical  movement. 

Tables  35,  36,  and  37  compare  frequency  of  change  with  timing  of 
movement. 

Tables  38  and  39  compare  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  ■v^th 
timing  of  movement. 

Tables  40,  41,  and  42  compare  average  change  per  change  with 
frequency,  amplitude  of  cycHcal  movement,  and  timing  of  movement, 
respectively. 

Table  43  compares  frequency  of  change  with  aggregate  change  less 
net  change. 

10  This  occurred  for  Criteria  L  and  N.  Measure  L  relates  to  the  peak  month  before  ■downturn  daring 
the  period  January  1936  to  December  1938.  For  158  series,  or  more  than  two-tenths  of  the  total,  there  was 
no  downturn  through  December  1938;  hence  groups  I  and' II  were  combined.  Measure  N  relates  to  ag- 
gregate change  less  net  change  for  the  period  January  1926  to  April  1929.  For  198  items,  or  about  three-tenths 
of  the  total,  this  criterion  was  0.0;  hence  groups  I,  II,  and  III  had  to  be  combined. 

"  These  18  tables  present  what  appear  to  be  the  more  significant  relationships  betwec  these  measures. 
In  addition  13  other  tables  of  the  same  kind  (Nos.  46  to  58  mclusive)  have  been  prepared  end  are  appended 
for  the  convenience  of  those  who  may  be  interested  in  such  comparisons. 


lyO  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  44  compares  amplitude  of  movement  with  aggregate  change 
less  net  change. 

The  relationships  depicted  by  these  tables  are  summarized  in  table 
45.  This  table  shows  the  extent  to  which  decile  ranking  varies  for 
each  pair  of  criteria.  For  example,  criteria  C  and  D  are  compared  in 
the  first  line  of  this  table.  Twenty-nine  percent  of  all  the  items  in- 
cluded fall  into  the  same  rank  for  both  of  these  measures;  63  percent 
show  a  difference  of  one  rank  or  less;  81  percent  show  a  difference  of 
two  ranks  or  less;  89  percent  show  a  difference  not  exceeding  three 
ranks;  none  show  a  difference  of  nine  ranks.  (Relationships  involving 
criteria  L  and  N  were  omitted  from  this  table  because  the  grouping 
of  deciles  prevented  the  use  of  this  technique.)  Obviously  a  high 
degree  of  uniformiiy  between  the  ranking  for  any  pair  of  criteria 
imphes  a  close  relationship  between  the  two  aspects  of  flexibility  meas- 
ured. The  relationship  to  be  anticipated  on  the  basis  of  purely  chance 
distribution  is  also  shown. 

The  significance  of  these  comparisons  is  summarized  below: 

Depression  decline  compared  with  extent  oj  recovery. — There  is  appar- 
ently a  marked  relationship  between  the  extent  of  decline  between 
1929-33  and  the  percentage  of  recovery  from  1933  to  1937.  The  per- 
centage of  items  falling  into  the  same  rank  under  both  criteria  is 
almost  three  times  as  great  as  chance  expectation. 

Relationships  between  various  aspects  oj  timing. — There  was  some 
tendency  for  prices  which  declined  early  in  1929-31  to  recover  early 
during  1932-34.  Approximately  the  same  degree  of  relationship  exists 
between  the  timing  of  the  depression  low  (1932-34)  and  the  recovery 
high  (1936-38)  and  also  between  the  timing  of  the  1929-31  peak  and 
the  recovery  peak.  However,  these  correlations  are  not  very  close. 
Only  16  percent  of  the  items  fall  into  the  same  rank  for  criteria  J  and 
K  as  compared  with  chance  expectation  of  10  percent.  Evidently  the 
order  of  price  movement  changes  materially  at  successive  turning 
points. 

Frequency  oj  change  and  amplitude  oj  cyclical  movement. — It  was 
observed  in  the  course  of  the  general  discussion  of  price  flexibility  (ch. 
II,  pp.  31-32)  that  prices  which  change  frequently  show  a  marked  ten- 
dency to  move  widely  in  response  to  the  broad  upswings  and  down- 
swings of  general  business  activity.  Tables  31  to  34  present  four 
aspects  of  this  relationship.  The  closest  correspondence  is  evidently 
between  criteria  A  and  F.  Presumably  this  is  due  to  the  fact  that 
both  of  these  measures  are  affected  by  seasonal  movements.  In  cri- 
teria H  and  I  the  effect  of  seasonal  forces  is  largely  eliminated;  the 
former  is  based  upon  annual  price  averages  and  in  the  latter  the  same 
month  of  each  year  is  used.  Table  45  shows  that  the  pattern  of  rela- 
tionships between  frequency  of  change  and  each  of  these  two  measures 
is  very  similar  but  is  not  as  close  as  that  existing  without  seasonal 
correction.  The  comparison  between  criteria  B  and  I  shows  that  the 
relationship  between  frequency  and  amplitude  of  movement  is  of  about 
the  same  order  whether  frequency  be  based  upon  a  period  of  relatively 
full  resource  utilization  (measure  B),  or  upon  a  longer  period  including 
a  major  downswing  (measure  A). 

The  Pearson ian  coefficients  of  correlation  for  these  comparisons 
have  also  been  compu<^ed  on  the  basis  of  unranked  data.     These  are: 

Correlation  between  A  and  F  +0.83  (standard  error  is  0.013). 
Correlation  between  A  and  H  -+-0.74  (standard  error  is  0.018). 
Correlation  between  A  and  I  +0.77  (standard  error  is  0.01  3). 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         171 

The  correlation  between  frequency  of  change  and  the  National 
Resources  Committee  measure  of  depression  sensitivity  (criteria  A 
and  E)  is  somewhat  lower;  the  coefficient  is  +0.70.  The  difference 
in  principle  between  the  National  Resources  Committee  criterion  E 
and  criterion  H  has  been  pointed  out  above  (p.  167)  and  may  explain 
the  reason  for  this  variation. 

Frequency  and  timing. — Tables  35  to  37  show  a  distinct  relation- 
ship between  frequency  and  the  timing  of  change.  Table  45  indicates 
that  this  relationship  is  of  approximately  the  same  order  as  that 
between  frequency  and  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement.  Thus  for 
criteria  A  and  J  (frequency  of  change  and  timing  of  the  1929-31 
downturn),  24  percent  of  the  items  show  no  change  in  rank,  while 
for  the  comparison  between  frequency  and  timing  of  the  depression 
low  (criteria  A  and  K)  22  percent  of  the  items  are  unchanged  in  rank. 
The  Pearsonian  coefficient  of  correlation  computed  from  the  unranked 
data  is  +0.59  for  the  comparison  between  A  and  J,  and  +0.49  for 
the  comparison  between  A  and  K.  These  coefficients  are  materially 
lower  than  those  relating  to  the  comparisons  between  frequency  and 
amplitude  of  cychcal  movement;  however,  this  difference  may  be 
partly  due  to  the  fact  that  the  relationship  between  frequency  and 
timing  seems  to  be  curvilinear  rather  than  linear  in  character. 

Amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  and  timing  of  change. — Timing  of 
change  seems  to  be  related  to  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  in 
approximately  the  same  degree  as  it  is  to  frequency  of  price  change. 
This  is  shown  by  the  pattern  of  tables  38  to  40,  inclusive,  as  well  as 
by  the  summary  in  table  45.  The  Pearsonian  coefficient  of  correla- 
tion between  criteria  I  and  J  (cyclical  flexibility  and  timing  of  1929-31 
downturn)  is  +0.58;  that  for  the  comparison  between  cychcal  flexi- 
bihty  and  the  timing  of  the  depression  low  is  +0.54. 

Change  per  change  compared  with  frequency,  cyclical  flexibility,  and 
timing. — Tables  40  to  42  show  that  there  is  no  apparent  relationship 
between  the  amount  of  change  per  change  (measure  M)  and  other 
criteria  of  flexibility.  This  inference  is  borne  out  by  table  45,  which 
shows  that  for  these  three  comparisons  involving  criterion  M  the 
distribution  closely  parallels  chance  expectation.  Apparently,  the 
amount  by  which  a  price,  changes  when  it  does  change  is  not  an  indi- 
cator of  other  aspects  of  its  behavior. 

Aggregate  change  less  net  change. — Tables  43  and  44  show  a  high 
degree  of  relationship  between  aggregate  change  less  net  change 
(measure  N)  and  both  frequency  and  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement. 
Unfortunately  so  large  a  proportion  of  the  total  number  of  items 
shows  an  aggregate  change  less  net  change  of  0.0  that  it  is  impossible 
either  to  present  a  summary  of  these  relationships  in  table  45  or  to 
compute  a  meaningful  coefficient  of  correlation.  Nevertheless,  the 
similarity  of  pattern  shown  by  tables  43  and  44  make  it  probable  that 
this  kind  of  measure,  combining  as  it  does  elements  of  both  frequency 
and  amplitude,  may  serve  as  a  useful  index  of  pric(;  behavior. 


172 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


'«oe4'«-«i  '0<  a> '<<  o>  to  00  o  acoO'<«-o«e4cO'«'«ooaoMoooaoo<oeoaoocic40 

^  tp-^^?^^  eo  »o  »-*  ro  >d  ci  ^  AOodoo -^o6c4ioocc>c^  coc^  t^o»(^Me4  ^a»*c  ^ACJo 

•iSiNNrH  « .^  c«  e»  S5  rt  «  ^  CO  c»  ■«' CO  ■*  lo  CO  c5  .-I  N  -nRr^t-i  ■-loO've^n 

^  ^t^Nooo  r-i  rH  t>.  I— ^  N  t-  (x>a>^aooot^ooc4t>0'4it.co>o>Hoaci  t-aot>m<-<C4oo 

IS  ujiotocom  o6>dcd'dad>o<s  '^0(»c^'oc4Ti<oo^co^co^too>nrJmi--<<dcoe4oo 


eT>^^^^^ 


t.  tcr  «  t* 


t^flCiDt*h>r«aot«QO-aoN.ot*-r-oo'iD<0<o 


v^i^t^oS^CN^*      cO^«s<^otf^«^«^<#K^'s)aNos^^^'i5N«ve^^ve5Nr2^'«Kofl^eV'Ors3>^« 


^^^M  v^^MvMvT*^  ^^ri  vM  vM  y£4>^  vM  -Tl  ^C^  %£4  >M  ■>^  n^  >M  ^  sT*  ^  Nf)  ^  •^  >M  o^  ^T*  >^  >«4 


Noo^t-.-<«"<'i~     ■>ii<e<5r-^eoTj<o»t»«o>eoeoot~«C'Oi-ioo'Ooo>et~eooo 

t^Qoiioanr-^^     co'«od>oooQmT)!coe«it-:<-<>4^a>cj>o^aoQ'Hadi^o^ 
^3>oioSio^     to>S>0'*'<<>oeo^Hvt-i«u5e^r~u3t»ioirt3oot^«x5to 


ooc»50>o«>e^o      03'HTi<iOT(it-eocOT»"0-^eoioeoo>oo>ot^o>oOi-icoN<0'-i 
•o  >Q '« CO  <o  >o  CO      "O  CO  CO  ^  CO  us  e>»  CO  ^  CO  CO  1-1  CO  es  to  "J*  o  «  CO  o  <o      o^'* 


t»o>-ioo« 
coaid'Ji-i 


lo  vH -^  a»  o)  kc  o 

•O  0»  >2  5^'  00  CO  Q 
CO  CO  CO  t^  t^  CO  ^ 


o^oc^oa»e*QO■-'eo©e^>oeoa»^"eoc^eo•o•-laoaoao■-"o> 

oocJcQ'«>de<iaicooriaW'^cdo^r~^>aeoeorH<-'°coi^'^ 
t^co^^^*o^«cou^c0^r^rau^eooo<o^«vcocooooo^-t^t^ 


r~oot»t»ce 


CO  r^cot^r^c 


o  «o  CO  o  N  rt  t-  >o»^eoe<'<»<coeor-oooeoco«»oopcoo>t- 
c5 1>^  d  00 1~  >o  "i  •-«  CO  cp  06  CO  •"<  t>i  Q 'p  1^  ><»  M  eo-i-i  «■  CO  ^  ci 
r^  CO  b>  S>  lO  t»  CO  CO  CO  9 1«  CO  U9  CO  S  <o  t^  CO  <o  CO  00  00  r>  t>  t> 


73 

;3 


e<OO>0rH 


O  0>  0>  O  CO  o  •<«< 


COOON 


<ooooco«"eov^ococ«c«'"*oooocO'<<'«<oo^ 

«>ooo>oo>o>i~^i-4do>rH<>piio^cQcoco^>or^ 
C4  ^  rH  74  CO  Ci '«■  i-l  CO --I  CO  <o  l»  ^  CO  S  S       ^^-^ 


cooo>o>o^ 


-H  «  t»  ■♦  OS  O  t~ 

d  go  t;  r^tr  "5  « 


»-<i-H«CO< 


coco'4<>o>nacocoiococ^aor~>oc«o>coo><OrHO>ococ>ico 
rf*  S  ^  ?j  S2  3?  g  <*  ffi  >»  SJ  ?a  t:  t:  w  OS  r)*  t;  ^  tC  S  SJS 


^00      t^cot^ooooc»c>op<co*coa>'<<i^-<t»eo»o  w«  CJ05C 


CO  »0  O  t*  CO -^  OS 
lO  t^  CD  CD  CO  >0  >0 


C*CON^OaaWt^»0<DCDO»Ot^05003»OCN|WcDQOOOC« 

S*uSir5ooosos«or>^b-i^»6cflt>oicc-HeoM3tDC^Q'Hi*^QO 
»o»ocD»ocD^»o^eo«C'^»oNt^^t^»o»o^eooo»«   w5 


CO  CO  CO  coco 


Oft  oa  a»  o)  00  oa  oa  o>  Aa»t*o»cDasaba)cDoae^^'^^jgkOagco 

CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO   CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  c~ 


*-H  ^         COMC 


5^00  OOC 

3  wrtSse 


ua  lo  to  lo  ko 

O  Ok  Ott  0>  Oft 


SSc 


lo      lo-^^     iioeo  *o»o --H  CO  ^oiocoeo  •-*  o»oeo»«co '^oO'^os 

OS        ^^03      iO>00OaO)O)0C'd^(NCO^^t>>CDwO&00O>O>Q>b*O)QO 


s 

n 


•a. 

59  a  o  oa  >>r; 
JmOOP5^ 


3  2  .: 

o  S 

tt-a 

a  > 
2  OS  o 


gJ 


iS-oS- 


■  ■  ^ 


.2  fen 


S  03 


00 -0 

_2  S 


^  M  O  03 

la-s 


III 

$  03  C8 


-",«' 


i-t  CO  iQ  t*  oa  ^  5 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


173 


lOtOC^Tfiao  wo       C4       00       C4       ^OOOOO^       MO      Til  C4  O^  ^  00  CO  C4       oc^ioooe^oo^o^oo 


coSicjeo  me!!  to      -h      ooogiogco      ^^^      o -^  »-<  o»  ■* « o>  ob      o>  •«<  <o  ro  ■-"  "-"O  co  oo  "S  N 


•<«1  CO  1-J  -H  CO 

^_^0  »-i  Ob  ^  ^^(D  ^^0»  O -^  M  W  •*  C^ -^  M  O  »0 

o^'^.-Jci'^cDcocd'^cocooii-Iec^iococSt^ 

C«    (D   OO   o  t^ 

t^  .-K  fJS  ^\  C^  *^ -^  C4^  r^  C^  i>^  vi^  M3V  rN  ■0' >  t0^  M  N  oCTs  0^ 

r^o(r-k$^«vc(rv>5^|5^e$^eKwso!N^^  ^t^^r-k«-Ka^«s 

^^ 

S^H^ 

*Ss  e<3^  «^»^  cV- ris  d^  w^  5^  ^ -Js  e^N  e5^  c^ 

2;s 

9  a  o  o)  01 

r^cOC400&  CO -^  CO  »-<  t^  CO  OS  OS  t>"  00  «D  (O  CD  i-H  «0  <-l  O  00  N  00  CO  ^  •-*  O 'H  lO  WS  C^  »0  00 1^      I  t^»OCOCl  rH^  CO 

^-Hid'^'eo  u?Ti<-*cDrtidcsoc«'«r>ooQa6'oa6co-HO>t5  >or»ocoo-<eooscDodt-^^    icDt>^cOTi<od«og; 

iCOseC*00  to  O  l^  C^  t^  C*l  »-»  OS  t*  CD  i-<  00  CD  CD  CO  ^H  r»  ^  CO  »-ICOOOBCONt*CD  W  •-•'^^  ^^^  >O^hO00»-< 

coos-^ooi-H  ■oc-J'*o-<eoe»<3-H'>ri'^"QOso6osoc--oso6  rtio'ast-^oiaJ^^Of'C^^'odeooqes    'csijcj 

■3<  CO  •-<  ?!>  T)<  leoco^  j.Jl'*  J5m      ■*^tDeoco3>-icort  NMeSc<N«-**i-i-*io  4.     i-<c5co          cow 

^OSNCOO  10  Tt<  ■*  OS  OS  to  t- OS  N  ■"! -- "5  O  t^  O -H  O  ■»!"  »-"  >»"  CD  CD  O  CO  ■*  CO  >-l  N  ■-<  N  0>  "O  "O  O  *  OS  >0  00  N 

S'coxjcoo  cJTiicDTii    ■<N'fl>'e3Tt<Ti<Qoci-H-«ii-iaoc^'coo  NC^ujidodoocoeacpgJgC'H^goeooda'oeo 

uSM-S-fiS  comco^      rt  loSco -Hi3>ooO'*oo3— lioio  co co eo •* co « is co N co co 9 •>»< « Si -« »-i M ■»■<»• 

00>C-^CDO  C0>0^  t^OSOt^OSC900*-)CI  ^^  b- F-iCOOO  O  ^  lO  O  CD  r«  t«  00  Ob  C^  C^  CO  CO  lO  lO  CO  CO  OS  00  t>  kO 

S"eocd>oo  "dcocouj    'n-ifcit^>oa6cie^-«cideiuit^  c<i'«i'rtirfooQ<oqoceeooO"-H'icoodo'oO's'2?2 

S5i-H-5"S5  eScoeort      iiiSSco      K  <c  oo  ■*  oo  t- —i  "5  •"  co  co  ■^i  ■«<  S  ^  C  55  m  co  3  ■>«>  ■»  M  co  ■>»<  i-i  i>»  ■<"  •* 

t-tr-OOi-^O  CSW  OCOOO  •-<  COCOOS  CDt^cD  coo  CDOOOO  W  CO  ■<*•  COOO  t^CDOCSCOCDW^OCONOf-lCDCl  00 

^cO"-<c<co  I  C0CO.-1  I    I  ifrtcs      CO  CO  t~  "«<  t»  lo --I  CO  ■-<  «  N  c5  «  Pi  c5  CO  CO      coco  |       ^nm          eo--" 

ooosooso  o  c<  c^  "o  t*  o  ^  o  CO  00  »-<  •-<  CD  *o  CO  i-^  t^  t^  »-<  00 1^  c<  00  00  ^H  ^ -^  O'^  c*  oco  cow  ooco  w  oot" 

S*  ^  h^  C4  c5  I^O  OO  *^  W  CO  O  00  00  COb*  OS  to  OS  00  CO  O  O  lO  t^  CO  OS  00  "^  •-^  OS  f*  00  CO  OS  c4  CO  ^H  ci  CO  *#  «  rH 

5     S©  SuSaSsS      ScoS-gi      SJoSojioSc^SHp.  •*  co  35  5*  iS  lo  o  oo  m  o>  os  co  oo  co  >o  to  ci  eo  ^  eo 

t^f^t^OS«  « -^CS  OSCDOO  COOOCO  t^O«  ^  W  CO'^'^O  ^ooot^otoo  ^o*t*  Wt^OOOSOOtO  ^OSO 

g"ioeo»-^Q  eoo6>oo6ei      t^e-Jc^'cocicocoodcd^cooscD  Os'ooo^j^oodas'oQQ'cjjgeoosjjar-jfflooo 


lOOS 


«CO 


OSPJ 


:SS 


o»oacogQu3      oo»o^eooosoco»-«oioogot^ooMi-HN 


COCOMCi  ^  ^ 


CCCO        CCC4 


McO'<i<03'^o>eo»oeoect*OiOOeO'^oo5^-oooo 


ss^ss 


CO  O       CO  CO  cc 


goeo^ootjooc 


Tj^-^QCCDN        ■^t^cD»C«Oi-<W5'^^»-H»ONiOC*«»OQOOOC^ 


OiOiCOCO^         ^H^H^i 


03         1— (  1— (  OS  03  03  CO  CO  00  •-<  00  t* 


SiSSS 


iio^Ar-a:C4C^Q^iO)-icoio<ou3 


SSSi 


•oC4ooaocoooasaoioc^C4>ocoiO'«<eo 


ss 


■OHiSfe 


a,->^  a>  a  a  ^ 
"oja  o  >  o 
EJ«QOWPh 

Q 


-^-J'^- 1'  a) 


^Js  ^  fc  -1  a  3  « 
aooZZro  So  fc 

gPQP5pqBPQUOO 

o 


03  V 


■^11 


fell's  "3" 


j^  j^  t."  I-"--  3 


o  " 


a>  S  bo  p.  Q.X3 

o;g  g  o!  08  o 

S  p  "SScd  —  '^'O'O 

O  O  |i4  -^^  "*  H^  CO  03  03 


«  3  a  «  8  «•§  a 


'O'CaoJeOoP.O.m"- 

o§p'0'0'0'a'0-9§ 
o  3  0-2 .2.2^.2  "  a 

o3o8cO>-<>-'^^iM03a3 


II       ii^ss  S8ss$s;ssss||ss22^22  Ss^lS^BSSBiSsssissss 


174 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


^US'^tOOO'^'^'^dM'^OO 


•<<  N  «  ■tfKO  O  <D  ©  00  <0       -O"  •«)<  O  to  •*  O  N  W       O 


0>  W -^ 'H  t^  S  ^  O  OOT^  "5  ^  »-•        rH  00  P3  ^  ^  to  t^  y  ^H  «a«        00  00  ^  C^  CO  to  i-H  »-t       » 

1-1  rH  N  CO —I  i-l  •-!  -H  ■-(  N  W  ■->  i-l  •-'  ■-'  .-l«l-l  11  eS 


tO«'000-<|<'<'-<l<0-HOQCt-M 

ujiotoo6uj-^-^coc«9c&t^^'^ 


I     CO   1-1  ^  oi  00  CO  C* -<  0>  CO  ■*  to  00  N  O  0>  >0  00  O  N  ^^to 

■  C/.5^e<s  wco  cit-<tDe>ac<5odi-<tO'<i<t^c4od^^t»teeoe>i  wci 


(DCSOC^(3i'-*C0O«0C000*00>  CSt^r.00WC0»O'^»0Ol^N'^09C000*OC000»0?et^^*0»0eO 

Tf«C0C*3:^*OcO»O'^'^»O»OC0CO  Ti-t         CI»-HCOC0»OMCSC4W»OC0CQi-t»0         ■<ir»0'^lO               COi-l 

t^  ^  kO  t^  r«l  to  00  t^  1^  CO  04  00  t^  r-^  »-i        fsl  tO  •rf  O  "^  t^  00  •H  ^  O  P<  1^  <0  t*»  ^  »0  CO  h^  c4  00  CO  O  CO 

»0  0>  0>  C»  »0  >C  •»**  CO  U3  t- »0  00  00  W -^        O  <-«  t^  «5  CD -^  r^  CD  CO  ^  CO  00        CJ        OiCD^     |CO«-Hb-CO 

^^         ^  ^  CO  CO  •-<  i-(  N -H  I                 .1                     CO                            1-i                     W               T-ir-i     I 

l^-^  000000*0  Wt^»M»-(0  i0<0r*0000t*McDOWC000C0>0rHC0>0t*05»0»-iC<C0C0'«t*^ 

o><-J»dcot^o6^^^cou3^cDC^i  ^^•^r^^-^^o»Oit^o^*'-*c^^^*'^ooi^o^»oQcoo»-^'^^•^ 

is  *0  ■* -^  lO  25  CO  »0  »0  CO  »C  ■*  »0  ^^-^   ^  CO -^  »0  »0  Jo -^ -^  •«*  U5  CO  CO  CO  CO  1-t  CD  iO  uS  00   i-l-^W 


»OO000CC00S0C0Sb-0»0&CD0a 
COCOCOCOCOCOCOCOCOCQCOCOCO 


^ooo*oo>oo-^oco»-tt--b-'^'*Noowo»«DOs-^t*oao 

€0        COCOCO.-<C*C<ClCS«»-t        CO— ("tCO        CO  CO 


)^^'«t*c»r^Q»OQco»o»oeo 

>t>>O^Odt^C090>^030%000> 


C*0'^»oa>'<*''^t^ooocDQQO'^cot*-^t^O'^c«'<*<'^r-t^w 

r-t       0»       Oa  0>  QO  CO  *0  *C  CD  iO  »0 -^  1-H  OS  •-«  ■*  t^  CS  OS  ^H  ^  fi  0» 


JMJ«i 


10:2; 

■otT 


j^'-gja-S-e 


si  .£3 


s 


■2« 


Q  uco-^iotot^aoasQi-iesco      ^>Q<Ot«oca>Oi-ic^ra^>5tor^oQS 
9 1-1  ^  ^'^^  ^  9 -^  35tou5u5      «&i6ti5«OkCto^co  to  toto^d  toS  to 


o>Oi-<e^co«<<>ocot^ooa> 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


175 


<&co^coooooo^oooo 


0»  ■*  «o  ■*  00  to  o  CO  t~  o      i)<t^O<CO^ 


coao>->  NMM 


CO  CO  «o  »-*  ec  r*  00  <D  00  N      cowst^csoous 
r^  00 -^  CO  id  ci  M  d  c^ -^      oJo6odcoo6»d 


»5s -3k  e^  ^  w^. -3s.  ^>.  ^  cflS  c 


t^f^pJv^v^St>^|2^vX.i^v4s        O9S0S  JK^^c^^. 


OS  flO^  tjv  ijv  |Js  ^v  ^s  ^X  Cf^  ds 


s  «s  tOx  ^  t§^  ^^  eSs  « 


S?  ^i?  ^5?  "^  ^' "^  "^  ^^  "^ '^^      '<'' ^^  *<*  ^  S9  ^^ 


;s:R^jj°ssi;s$i:rs2 


S^^J:?:^ 


00t»»H00»<t»>OO>00'«< 
c!lt~'»SO«OW>J<<050M 

ooooM05«<5oo>-ie<« 

ect*^b»tDb»^l>-cpc4 

Ni^-oo'oeo.-iM-Hwo 

MC4coa>e<iooaooaoo 

06Q0»OidO00C0t^w5Q 

3>oo>oeoi-it^iomo>o» 

^Qt^«C'O&»OO5cp00«-t 

w  CO -^-vioto  rococo 


<«•  >o  00  m  o  00  o>  c^  C4  C4     OTi<o»OP»t~ 
^ooo6o6«d>dT)<T(N5D     od<3>«>:a>.-<<d 

W  N  ^  i-i  ^H  .-(  M  CS  »-l  N        CC  CD  to -Tf<  CO  t^ 


w»o«ooi-*cs^eoooo 
'*eo'^»c-HMC^r-Ncoco 


c^  a» 'tf*  ccrec  o  ^ -^  *-t  00      <Okcodto<oC4 


e0t-MtD00Ot~i-110t0 


si 


"5  *^  **?  C5  oi  ^*  ^^  ■^  c^  C3     wS  CO  »-I  oc  ^  o> 


WuS-^tOt^C^fHOOi^O 

•^oiotd'O'OOJoccco 
^m>5>o<-iccc^c4meQ 


O  >0  b- CD  "tf"  rt  o»  ^- «n  >-l       eO-fCIONO 
00 -^  <d  fj  •'5  ■-"  00  CD  CO  50      r^oo^-ioocDO 


tOO»-i05t^C^»-i^O'tf' 

'*'*ioiOi-icoWNcoeo 


•owo^eoto  wo-*o     totD>Qt-a>o 

K       i-l  in  e*!  i-H  c<  ei .-.  «       ©COCOtCiOI^ 


oo^^oo^co^oooo>o 

C^C<ltD»Ot^tdo»OCO'^ 

eocicoeo  .ifrJiN 


IOCS 

S7 


00  o>  00  00  a>  CO  C4  m  r- CO     >oco>oooc^ 

•6  .-<  CJ  00  i-<  00  Q  i-i  0»  lO   --QCOQt^^t- 
■*  W  CO  CO  CO  CO  io  ^  »-«      W  O  CO  ^  OQ  N 


00  ^  ^  O  05  t*  ""S*  ^  t^  ^ 

i^t>^<dcoocDcD3i;'a>cJ 

C0'*000.-CC4COIN«OIO 


0>       Oiico 

f-H  O  ^  00  CO 

CO     ootos. 


00  OS  CO  ■>*<  ©  00  .-I  M  N  t~      eotDCit~t~oa 

M  .-I  r-;  <d  CO  ^  o  ■*  es  ■*      coor^wt-ied 
eococort      r-i9c<ii-ico      r~  t>.  CO  "<<  CO  lo 


t~e>iiocot^o>oeotoooo 

C00CCCD'««O5^^»-^CDC^C^ 

'^^CO'^'O.— 'COCOf^COCO 


00  00  00  t*  t^ 

citde>i>o>rf 
e<"-i^eo"5 

+ 


OSOt^N-^OlOOQOOO^ 
CO  CO        CO  C>  CO  fl-Cl  i-H  M 


lO  •*  T)<  <o  U5  o»  00  CD  t^  »0       OOOS' 


e<i  CO  CO  p»  CO  CO 


C»COOOt.N©rH.-lCCiO 


l«CON»-<»HCOr*CDiO»0 

>a>c^ooioo>cor~coco 


^  0»  C  to  i-i  5<  ■^ -<  CM  ■*        CC«OQt^V< 

.-1      i-i  1-1  I-H  N  ■*je«  i-(  rH     oooa*t^ooe 


>o>>ot^^>oai'«<'«' 


is^ 


si 

not- 


_  O  ® 

■Ji  03  > 

aw  O    fl^    -^  ®    L* 

u.  C  u.  -w^  r"  '    — 


5  —  a*  o  -^ 
5PhmO 


:  3  O 

JO* 


o  o 


,  '.a  , ■  CD 

g-o  g  a  fe«  >  « 


^11^  « III  §-&|fel^^-? -sill « 

•O  05 

5  ^ 


Sg 

S  > 


.  w      ■ 

£2   :    at 
•852  S 


O  O  p 

..  §8«2« 

Q  ^  ^  <D  O   ID 


ccE-i        3mSS^S    fl 


f-iNeo3|io    5 


odqoooodSoooooooooo 


o^eo  or*  o  o  o  oe 


176 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


oot^ooeoooooooo 


0000    'O0oo<o<oaoc«a»^<oo^o^ -^  t^'vaoc><C4 

_  _        -  --^  uj  e^'  e«  >o  «■  CO  oi  ci  »-<■  t>:  t-i  ■*  ei  "(J  t^  eo  o 

■-106    'oooo  "oeowcc-^  oeoeoo     mt~     lot^a 


!»■.-<«  00  C^eov 


O  C  CD  OK  t«  f^  O 

/06  CO  ec  06  «d  m  ij* 


m^e«5>o«DOicJ>d«>"«<««>de>5MC>eoTi<e<i 


«N    t  c5sodKe^^dNeT^^e5s^«N     ^»2s»3^ 


V^  ^  (^  tOs  utv  ^  esN  <^  ^  cSn  ^  i-f^  40s  t^  <r^  ov  *^  vs  ^ 


se^seK^Ksflffseo^t^^^ 


wvc*^  ^s  ^Ms  eo^r2\lvs^i^p5^  wN  w^  «y^«^  c5sm^  w^  ^  «fs 


e  (x  a>  o  o 


^MNOffvciSsuy'flSscSswsodscS^^ns      MSeJsuK 


9oa>»oo»ooooiO)Oai»a>o>a»» 
ujs  ,j«v  er»«s  0^  osN  ^  i-K  efls.  er^  i^  ws  iij^  ws  CIS  ^ -^  t^\  ^ 


«0     i»H      I  >0  O  Oi  O)  CI  t~  ■<»<  0>  00  O       MtT^ 

N    imosot-:odec.-<«'«5<D     i^>o« 

^      •        CO  CO  C^  09  C4  C4  CO  CC  CO        lOCfllO 


rH.-l<«<      I  d  C<9  00  r~  >0  >a  03  to  CO  ^  to      it^W'C 


O  <0  >-l  10  <0  O  "5 '«".  W  "S"  o  t- 

cocqT^cocoeoecMNTfieciN 


050e<ic>t~cct~o»e<<ooo>oo«DOt^<o^co 

05ec^*»Ci-*i-HCD'T^ca»ciN;odgDOi<dotN.*»0'1* 
'»«>*i-<jieO'*-^coe'<>oeOTf^«ec'*«e<5ii<'* 


CO  CD  "3  N  OS  o»  •-I  r- "5  o>  t^  o  co—ios 
w  r4  CO  *-(  o  t*' 1-5  CO  t-J  r-i  r^  t^  i-ie^fH 
■*N      Tf  coe^i<«  Ncocoeo      ■oco'O 


«o>cD-*ot~o>t»c<it^i-icooo>oo^>oooe« 

»-Jt^-<*5ioo6t^oi-^'c»oi'-5t-HOt^o6cpQCOQ 

cD"<«u5T»iT»>'*T»'««OT)<cocoeo'«>>o«>ow>5 


>ooooieo'*<o»>-cosoN 

e-t    I  CO  e4  ■»!<  -H  «■  t-:  CO  «■  qi  CD 

^  CO  cc  ^ 


1  t»CO»H 
«M  N  CD 


eoioi-i 

ric6ci 

eoeo      uscoio 


^00COOSt^»D00»C^t^OSC0MfHO5^»CN00 

T-Jod»o»dodt^'c»coeoos»-;w»-Io6odcDO'^Q 

CO^iC^^-^Sl-^CltO^CDCOeO-^lOC^ICWtlO 


OaCD        ^  OW  o 

wi  iQ  o  o  c4  co'  00 
■««<cq      eococoeo 


uici  «-i  Ob 
N-U"  cof5 


100  00 


OOOCOO'-HC^IOSTj^kOCDOOCDIOOOOOCDCOCD 

co"  00  w  -^  ts^  o  c4  c<i  t^  c4  eo'  wi  CO  ^'  CO  00  »c  •-*  t^; 
■<»'re'«'eoeoeococ^-«"cOT(<Ti<e5eo'^'<co'Vco 


ec  ■*  00 1~  ■><<  o  t~  i-i      eo^os 

oeo'^"-<«0'OCJi-i<Jc>      eiod 
-   -^ i-iT)<oo»>o     ocoa> 


>  CO  00  i-l  •«)<  00 « 


corti-<ooscot~.co-!j><oooooooococ»eo'»'oo 
op  b"  ?^_S;  S  S9  r*  SS  r*  3;  S  I"*  S;  S3  f^  S  f" 


5 -1 1^  r~^ob  o  M  t- e 


)  ^  t~  Tt<  e^  o  o  t- 


os'oeoMt^coi-'ooocooooos      ooiiot>-ocao>e^>ooast»oot~ocaoiciooc^i-iM'*'co 
■*ideo^cDOsoiococ«t~;coododTi<      e^'oT)!N's<ocdcDNOode<ir-;cD'*cdOi-<'«ft-;c6i-^>* 

>0'>rt<CO'*   f>  1-1  CO  P5  CO  CO  «  «  CO  CO   lO  N  lO  tO  CO  «3  ■*  ■*  10  ■*  ^i  CO  «0  •>«<  >0  M5  CO  ICl  Kl  ■^  ■'f  "5  lO 


^i-iioc<)0'-<odcococ><oeoia 


"S<0'-ieoo»Oi'Qt~-oo»ioioeD>9<>-iooco 
—  -*      coco      <-io      Wi-ieo 


<  O  "-I  CO  o»  OS  "Q 


03  ^  cocoes  co*^0^*    'Oir^o»-t 


goMcct^oii-iioooeocoiocooa'cot^ooo 
t~ooc4co>-i>o--ioocooso»i-i-*<oc5iocoeB 


^pqSStHEHfqSSo«CC)POCCESoSSop4^PHEraKSro£^E-i 


cor~ooa>Q<-4C4co-«>o«Qt.coo>o     ^oco'^iiQcot^coaso  o-<t<>o«DE-ogo>ooio«or-oo 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


177 


00     w^     e»     0000     <c«         i-iooO'*>o     oo«do«o«d^oooo     ^oo«oo«     o  «o  f  ■*  ■*  ^  <o  «c  oo         <Ct»i     «o 
c^oob^     scO'-Joooicoor-^f^ot^'^      idpr^irioitDoociooS'Hmi-ito     iot-^>rit~.'r."50C>«Crtoo«i-HOo6 


mnein 


Mi-JTiiweocsodcoJr^eiciwci 


rtNifirtOst-eDe^Tfiooust-cit-. 
t^  ciiM  00  i-i «  n"  00  -^  i-i  ei  f-i  ei  fh 


««Kt2^ffK^      oNocKt^3scK 


^•^ 


r^q^      (^         dscKGN«T^d^cKCT^0ff^^U7^t3\CT^.C^^ 


^V^gS^^CK        fiKc5^<iKi3^«Ke^^«$S^^fN 


e¥v^^eT\     ^^^cV*^vs3^^^^t5CtSspKt>te*v     tS\^c5^i5^^«5f^i5vo!K5v«N«N«Se^ 


^^  '^'>f]  vCO  >C0  >M  ^«4  oM  ^  oXO  ^9  tXi^  vrt  nM  >fO 


ccF-i»oeiGOo6Qt^o^*<p*oo>^ 


t«t^t0r*00CCCDC4C0C3>0'^O0b 

odododo»r^b^ccoae>orHi-4QOO 

C0C0C0*^C5NC0C0C0'V^^^»O 


c4cpi^t><d'^»ociciHc5Nt^^C| 


^s^^$ 


<0  ^^  CO  ^^  rH  ^H  OA  t^  h»  ^H  ^  ^  05  O 

eoN^ec-ii-icowcccc-^^-^ 


ooeD'*foot*Mt^eoo»ooo»ocoo»t^ 


NOONt^ 

g'daoei 
e»5»o»o 


^ec.-io»e<5<o«i«o>N>-i<oooo 


QOUStHCOOOCOCOCC^DCOCJ^C^CO 


5«o      eoeo^ 


»e<5'<»'«-*-*-*x5lO 


COOO-<r>OOOI^COOC<90QOOOOO> 

M*oo>t>t>*dcD«^o^coo^ad^'^^ 
■»»<  t»  lO  M  « -^  w  fS  «D  F-i      eo>o>oc4 


^  CC  »H  ^  06 

co-^xje^od 

■9*  CO^  CO  ^ 


<C5  tsTic    I  id 


rHmt^MtDc<5«oo«ooioe<i'o 


idciOQOt~idc«oQQOe»5o5aSa-^id 


-<t>coid 


•flie«t»«o->»<«c«eo«D»ooooM 


^ooNmcao<o<oa«ot^ 

S'^cd-^CJor^cDOidb^ 
e>5N-*»«i-ieceoeo« 


•"I'OO 


ooMtooooe^eooc^c^ooiaooio 
o  -H  o  '»<  «D  id  .H  c5 1-'  00  o5  SB  id  Q  CJ 


idoS^ujid 

OOiOM       'W 


OOM     iCO 


lOlOiOOOW«<<DOO>OOi-lODO> 

apida^oidcDQ'-H^ai^Qo^id 
BtaoSto^^ooor^oboooo 


« •*  o  ■»•  r- CO  •*  ■*  "5     or~o»>-io 


ssgs^sig^sii^s^jgss 


1  T  :j-4<c4a><0'-i  lOTtit^o 


o o CO t~ lo OS 00 i-i t^  t^ lo lo e> i-H     o>-c*    i  oN"-"-^  <o-Hooe»^.-<r- 


Q«ooiQ»eiooioioo»rH«  ■>* 00      c>t-!2    '  a?eoo?25e'**£3'=2<5U 
■Si  ■♦  eo  3  CO  M  eo  CO  CO  CO  •«" -"il  •*  •*      -w'toto    iw^coeoto  •<nai3co 


"  <0  00  O       ^  -V  MUX)  <OOCO<-lMCDt-OOOr>       lOOOO'^OXQiO'^M^OaO 


CON     CO 


i-H  w  tt  ^  ?^ 


CO  CO  CO  fH  1— (        t-H  CO 


SSSS    SS^S^j52^2?3SgSS    SSSSS 


t»  5(5  OS -.»<  Ej  CO  N  o  1-^M   eo  N  CO  lo  Tji  CO  OS  lo  lo  lo  » >«•  12  o  00 


•-i«4^<-i<^<-ii-ie4e4coco 


>O>00i-lrti6r-4.H-" 


9^-' 


.13  o,3  S  §1 


a  «  >>   l:^^ 
o  a  (s    s  c 

-HO   -a  I 

CO  ®  a>  10  ® 

B  S  S  a  a  1 

«>  O  O  4>  O  ' 


-II 

■  ©  w  ^ 

So  a 

a^aa 


o  o  o  o  o 


pp 


d  a  co-s 


c  i-  E  l:  o 

a  g  s  ©"o  05 


■§9^= 


-gife-sa 


ce  p, 
o  T  a  g  fe  g  I 


IDZ^  o  g  o 
cs  03  ►-  *;  a 
■3og,Sg 


ego  «-3-3  35  Sa  a  g  fe-sl  I  g  S  S|  I  ai§as  I 

53"S[a.  if 

COCQCOl>  O 


®  03  .g  .9 

S  f  fe  te 


s  * 


RnoS 


>  —  ««■«»•  V  *>  uus  o     o» o "I ei  CO ■»!< to <c t^  o £» 


S  in      cJSS 


Oi-iMCOiJ'iOtCh.OOOO  55 


F^  "^  00  00  00  00  cE  05  Oioa  C5  m5  cs  CO  o  «o  or-<f-4^Mi-(t-t^H^H^^oocsc^c<iirp  c«c5NcococococOcocoeoco«5;»-* 
iS*  (SNPJiSSSSrSciii^SoSS  Jo  to  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  =!  CO  CO  CO  e4  co  co  co  co  co  eo  co  eO  co  co  co  co  cO  co  2^ 
cic*  Ci  '"•  f^     n  coco  CO 


178 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


882 


Sco   r^ oc  eo  CO c*3  f-H  t* 

<  CO"-!  ^  »-C  1-1 


ooooooooooooooo 


ervcK^      eK«seTv 


«5^^s         c*^-^»^-J^<fl^»^'^^^^^0^ 


0^'c5^df^CT^e5NeT-.oiJ^d^3Nc*^cf^Os     '  d^cN 


;ssi 


3^.  "^  »ff^  <^  NN  o^v  otN  tdv  «<J^  «Tv 


'^  »C  CO  O  CS  CO  OM  t»  lO  O  00  O  »0  CO  ^  »o  »o 

^_L.io  "^or-^  00^  ci t> t>^ c^  ^ 00 *o  t^ <d t^ 

CSC^t^  O0COt>.  OOiO  O-^O'^^OeOOiNCD 

_t LI  i-i^rH  -^c^  ■^poioccMi-iM.-iec'^ 

■***  CO  •O  CO00»O  o>co  00  o>  ■^  C^ '«*"*  o  to  t*  «o 

(05000  edep^'  oJ  ooc^oiwcs-'t'cdocSf-J 

^  i-H  i-hWN  25m  ©lOt- «  <C>C0  ^  COQO  CO 

CDCOO  OOOC^  COC^  t^  to  ^  «  »0  CO  O  CD  r^ -^ 

uiiood  cdcdco  o  iQ  oi  CO  OS  CO  N  CO  CO  c5  Q  c4 

,-<  ,-1  pHCIC4  tC  C5  CO  »0  h*  CO  CO  CO  ■^  CO  00  CO 

OSOOO  COCOCO  «  t-»  CO  N  C^  W  00  »0  00  »0  C^l  CO 

co«o6  cit^co  oflcs)  c<io"^'-H'*<coooi^co 

I   I   I  rH  .-(  rH  iO  «  *0  CO -^  CO  W  i-<  W  ^H  CO  CO 

>-H -^ -*  O  ^  »0  0000  CD  <-f  OS  t^  00 -^  O  *0  OS  c^ 

odKo  iot^t>i  irf^l  o»ooc^os^cicco6a 

fh  c^eoco  h*  »o  CO  o  t*  CO  "  CO ''t*  CO  00  o 

ciwoi  oooeo  co^  ot-oosooc^  ^  «r* -H 

co*o^*  oicocd  tfJOi  (^^^'«*<uDi-icOTj<ocd 

.-I  ^  r-l  CO»-l  CO  CO  r- -^  CO  CO  CO  W  t-- CO 

+ 


.-ieooo^oooQoorooooo=t~P5N<o 


t^cocDoo.-t'^oasTfco^^oot^oo 
t^«-*0'^^'-<co»ccsooocjoe»ot-^ 

„^    -■ 4-    — '  + 


.-ia)oO'*o»a>Meot-.oot^c<Nto 


00«0000NO(NC^'>»'tD»O0CO'* 


5»  1-5  tp  o  <o  <o  o  c5  o  t-'  00  00  !-•  lO  o 


<D'<i<o®t-^o6o>o6e4<»<diocioo 


MO'*      ffioor^      t-^5 


st»o»i-<o>oer~oc 


CO  CO  CO   CO  CO  CO   CO  ^^   CO  CO  CO  CO  00  CO  CO 


sss 


OlM.-iOOr-(r-iC<00— lOrHOO 


•  OSO         ^rH 


S0»*t-"'1'C0CD03»O< 


i-«>eo     t»«     So oo o» 00 o> ■* 00 i-H ■>!' ! 


NP5r-li-l'*C9Tl<IOi-l"i(<CONTl<00 


•2  3 


s  2  §  2  3 


i?j  " '     ^  Tj  P^   (rt   w 

8^  £0(^  «". 


S  ai 


o  «  « 


T       •<      •" 


.—  —I  a  a 


s  gg 

"o  o  o 


3  a  3 

O  03  o 


O  a> 


« 

03X3 


Ic 


0=: 

03*0 

00 


S  >S  a"^ 
o  a  aaS 


m-  t?  S  O   J     m 


|£'3  2^^|^&S 


o<5 


1  CO  CO       CO  CO  CO       CO  * 


lA^tCtOO^tpCOCDC 

cocO€oco»3eocococ 


r-aoo»0'-Mco*io«eh~ooo>S'2 
<o3ot~t-t-t-fct~t^t~F-t-a5op 

CO  00  W  CO  CO  CO  00  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


179 


eoi-^oooooooooooooo     oooe^'©ooQ-Ha;o.--<o6o«<dQ05«N'oooooo6o6e<ioodi^e4  *•-< 


—1  >-l05«Dt~>0^^0  05CO®  C<5t~N  "OtO  t^  «  <0  O  «  lO  ■^  "O  i-H 

-  e<i  ei  c<  i-i  ^  rt'  ^  N  M  c4 1^  pi  ci  <d  ci  CO  vl^  w  C-  O^  c5od"-i«e4t>^c<i«ei 


^**oJ^N^N^o^o^»3^  I  Nvet^iff^dNeJ-o^*-^N^   off^eTv^^^x  1  WMri^irt^^v^lsioN(^^>i^s<^g(js^  (>ls  1  e^e^^s^^M^'-f^<^irt^^^iff^ttf^uy-(ffv 


N^^ovAvax^^^-^NoaktCv^jfxcsN^^tff^oiv   e«^^(ffscV-e*^^l've^e^t3vo>^rtxct^•J^•^rt^^^cK^vcJv-X^vtf^rt^c^e^^^^^^^^t^ 


tO\  cB**  r^  ar^  M^  aS^  oK  w^  ^  c5^  eV  *  a»N  e^  ej^  (ff\  C3N 


r^«-HeoccMcocOi-<ooi^*Of-fOscccoc<» 


N    OS  OS    <0  OS  CO  r-(  C^  to  i-H  t>»  rH  ^ -^J*  U5  iO  00  r-l  1^  W  »-H  CD  OS  O -^  OS  O  »0  00  OS  O 
»ftOW5MOC*3i-HC00S»OC^CCCDi-HQ»-H'H0d0S  *i-Hldoso6«Q>^"CflCDcd-^I-^0 


t~t-t^«ieccsioN>o";r^osooiooTi< 
^coooscsc^os»dosc6ocdccb-^poci 


■^        MlO<0-^C10-Ht^VTj"r»COOOi<5i-lC<l«IOO'ONW«Dt~..-lt^COi-l«OCO«« 

i-^ot^*^    'ot^t-^csTj«iOf-4^t^fO-TjJr-^csi£i^    'irsoso6oo'M"^ccosos"cdosf-^ 


«000»O^C^C0«D»-HM5M*Oi-HOSt^0000 
0'0^'^t^C^rH»-H»-^<DCC<OC4<NcdW 


CD       l^  t^        -^  rH  N  t^  CC -"i*  c^  c*  r^  C<J  OS  M  *o  C^  »-4  t>.  OS  O  M  t^  OS  W3  00  CD  OS  f-<  c^  *o 

^-"o•OT(ocil-H05cold^-;loO'^<lOc6T^■eooQOTM■^-;o^^<3it~;-He<3•-<os■os.-^^ 


>0  Tj"  00  OS —I  00  O     "9<  00  h- CT  M  1-"  OS  » 


1-1        NrHOSN0>b-«0WC>NOS0SCJCOC0«O'^00O0bOCDt-00'-"t~CqiOb-t-00 

0600606    ■|>^•4gBr^Jo6gocoOlOo6^^oso696e4c^■^^c>o6©o6N■T^<<^^TJIosa50^ 


Os-HCD-^0»OM      I  e^OS  CO  ^  0*C  OS  "3 


MCC(N  —IN 


)  OCO         CCC*5C 


t~«'>j">*coor-oor~.ONocqt~oo 
-HC*5QosO'^ost^oso6»-It^'^»oco« 


■*        0S-^c0C<lc0»O00CDO*^CDC^t^C^NOO00»OC0W^00CqC^»O'^iOC0Nt^ 
i-<Oc6cp     ■MOt^N»OCpi-<McdirfiCo6e<iTl5i-HOMOsOSC<5rH"irfM— ioOi-HOSO 


•-H  «       ««< 


•O  i-H  OS  ■*  "O  OS  "O       — 1  CO  CO  CO  O  CO  t- <N 


00       b-Or^t^'^CSeOOOeOO^i-tOOsO^—'OOO'^cDiOCOOOSOO'^OOb-'^O 
<OiO        t^  «0  *<»*  t* -^ -^  ^  »0  »0  O  W  T)<        W  iCtTi-hOO'^        owdoocooo 


O0"*CC^        Ot^        00O»OC<  ■^  CO -^  o 

+ 


CO        rtO        OOSOO  — 1^5^>  Ot^cD—icOOOr^  00rt«lO>OO        t-i(Nt~-^l 

^^oos■^oc^t^55g5»ocococDaQcooo6'<J*coooJ^°oo5^;20Nl55gcg 


-H  N  -H«N  MN. 


ic  coco      w  co< 


ooO'-'O^'-HNOcooO'-toooeo      ooot^*^ooosTf*coo-^co^Hr^t^o-^NcoooooO'^"^'^cscDosooco 


r-i—l-m        .H 


'SSS 


iO'nin-^'^^>oo'onc*e^c*>a<o<o     Nocoof5'fl<osooo3cDosoi5oocot~-t~>og»cos;or-it~t~cocoo5— inooo'Oosn 


eocoNco 


C0t~-t~>0«C0^Or-lt~t~C0C005— iNOOO'Ogt 


t^OOOSO— iNCOTfOOOsjHCO'O'     _* 

1-1  rt  — c  e5  c<  Jm  N  «  w  t- CT  CO  CO  CO    05 


GO  go  CD  00  00  00  00  00  S  OS  OS  C3S  OS  OS  OS  OS   S^OQ 
CO  CO  rt  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  W  CO  CO    CO  CO  ^  ^ 


MCO^»OCOr^OOOSO*-fNCO'^W5COt^OOOsP'-" 

OOOQQOOQa-^'-i'H 


180 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


OOO        00        OCXO^OO        <0  CO  04  <0  00  OO  CD '^        OOCS        i-H        CO        a-V  0)0000        nco^Ttr 

oVo<ooo-<MTj<oe^cirtO»ide>sMo'oode>50cDoe^      «oo      o«d^«<>ocpo>cD>o 

^-4  C*        ■**'€^N  »-i -^  Ol  CI  *-(        N  •*  I-H        a>  ^  CO        CD  00       ^  »0  CO  "^ 


mco      00      ^-l'^^^^^^      o  >o  m  e>5  o  O  •-<  US -H  e>)  iH  i~  •*      co 
n  ^'^i-i  On  n  e*  9J  ^cQ  i-i  ^  ^'  cj  i-i  oj  c4  ^  C4  c<i  to  •-!  t^co 


>00       Ot^OOOOMt^iOiO^ 

COM      •M  >d  c4  CO  ci  uj  (N  oi  e<i  P) 


>ro>*^        >^  vfO -^  stt  sfO  >M  •io  ^  ^ -xo 


«kd^^5^lrisH^>tf^5^•J^t2^K^K^4Nc*^eTv^^^^^^atf^e3^^^fl^u^      t^koBN      e5r>.t5\tX«^tSve^rXo*^(I^c^ 


■>»<i-it-0>00'OCDCO»COr-IO»'<>'>OOOmO->»'t>.t~i-cOCOO 


CO  ^      C4o^-cooo      IC0OC4CO 


o>t~-««<a><-(Osoot~^'-ioo>t~cooot-<0'*ot^'*>-i<»0'-' 

iOCOOCC      *^*OI»dcOCD^3C*^S^*OCOCOCO»^'^*c4cO'^CDCO 
1-H  M        COi-li-1  CO  «  IN  «  — <  .-I  CO  C5  rt -M  i-H        ,-iMf^ 


od"      c^o^- V 

-Hco      '«<^cd 


OdOCO 

^«.cd'fQOcoo5>oeo 

i    »0  CO  CD  O        COCO-^-*** 


OS'»1<OOOSOS^OOOCOOS»OCOCOOOCSOWCOOSCOOOC«COC^O 
h-l-<1*C0t^*<1^0i^C0'-4'^C0^*-^OC0  0iOt^OC50i-^t-'^t^'^ 

rt -H -H  oq  rt  CO  1-1  c5 -H  « t~  CO  CO  CO  OJ  o)  ■»•  o  «  e5  •-I      eiesco 


oo      oocouscoeo      cocooco 
i-ico      00  cj  oj  TjJ  e»  o  r^  ■-<  1-^  i>^ 

^_i  CO'Wt~CO        ■^lOiOlO 


O»OC0C0040SC0t^O00*OC0C0»O^CDOOO-*C00»C0^HlO 

os«3t>^og-^c4o5cocdt>coc<i'»j<F4u6c<i^*oQ"i'-HCOcoooooos 
X<  rtrtfSrt  cor-Je5rHNt~cocococ^  N-fl-eSi  o»mM      oScSco 


fH  c«      oo^»ococo      cocooaco 
oioo      00 ci ej ■* oi  o t>i oi t-i t>; 


(NOi-<I^'-«'«J'OCDOOOasOt^t>.'*COOIO*^OOOOiOO 


OOOOICD^        ^T'^'CO" 


*io  ■*      eocococo 


ocoa&oooooo09oo*oco*oooo^a3oacDA-^o*o-i«*oa 

-Hr»!odocoQcd'J<o>a5Sr-cooiodocDi-^odr>.'rtcd«D"ij<oo-«' 

C4  _  rt  3 -<  S  CO  CO  ■-<  CO  cj  w«r  ■«' ■<»<  CO  t~ 'J"  CO  CO  CO      •^■"("oo 


t~.oo  lOh-t^eo      eo>ct»>o 

^co      O^^rijrio^cD'gico 


*-«  CO  O^  CO  CO       03  o  o  c 


OSOIOS  090-^OCD  lOi-H  05  *COt^cO  COr^O  OICO  CO        0  04-^ 

co»«t^t^t^t^ocD»ot^3fgQOiosco-<i<«5odiooooow^ 

COr-l         Nrt>-lrHO«<OC'lCOC5rHrtCO'-li-ii-cC5         "  — 


««0        C«0OCOCO'-l        t^OOCD 
Tj*CO         ^  »0 -^  CO  t>^  O  ^  OQl^ 


McsN      rt  oi  coM^m      ■«»<» 


CO  CO  O  00  O  »  t~  Ol  Ol  O 'J' -a"  Ol  go  Ol  Oi  CO  t-- Tf  OS  C»  0»  IM  O  00        "OCD        0>0> 'OOOSMOOOQO 


rH  .-<  r-l  cocoes 


?-H  »-H         f-H  CO        CO  CO        CO  CO  c 


O»a5r^o-^o»o-^r*u5»oot^-^oot^  — WcooooN»ooo» 

■<f         COi-iC^  00 1~  US  CD  ^  rt  CO  CO —C  >-l  I-H         CO         CO 


eo^t^ge^wocot^OJ 
i-HOli-HOOOO       t^oocot- 


5    o  aft 


L,  <u  S  "  «;  OT 

3«i;  g^  «  i,  s. 

"mOfliraaaWOH&OW 


Is^ 


S^   CO       '       ' 


•is 

•-  o  cj  ?■- 


a.b 


no 


CD  f^  00  Oi  O  ^H  C4  CO -nfi  *0  CO  t^  00  OS  O  1-H  CS  CO -^  lO  CD  O O  i-H    OOO    OS  O —<  C^  CO -^ 'O  CD  t^  00 

CO  CO  CO  CO -^  ^ -"t* -^ -^  ■*** -^  ^ -^  ^  lO  »c  »o  W3  lo  »o  »5 1^  ^  CD      ^5>      CO  r*  r^  t- K.  t*  t*  t^  t*  r-^ 

^Jl  ^  ^1  ^  M*^  ^  HP  ^  ^  M<  ^  ^  ■^■^  ^i  Tjl  ^1  ^  ^  It*  U5  ^1  ^  CO  ^  ^  ^  ^  ^  ^ -^  ^  ^  ^  ^ 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


181 


«O'<!t<CO0O       COOO       O  00^50     I  ^DOO'^COOOW  c*  o  o 

,-).-.,-<      rHc^      CO  »ob»co    it-HiN'^aoweowwc^ 


<-i  O  O  GO  0»  CO  t*  04  U3  C4        U3  Oa  e>9  00  t^  t^  a»  04 

c*c4  w^^e^F-Joiwoi     ^eo»6^»d-^-^ci 


CO    *  r^  ei  00  '^  t>^  ^  w«6  ^  ^ 


04       lOt-HOO 


^^^^^-tOOCOCOO*^ 


ft       CDCOO)      1 1^  04  04  CO  CO  CO  04  Ol  i-i 


f5^w^ffl^-X^ctf\t^<^eS«3^       wserv|ws.(Jsc5^e5N^c^ 


»2^  Ks  rt^  c5^  c5n  c5h.pK  •J^  e^ 


N»  sTo -^  "^o  ^ -^ -^  y|5  "><o '^  ■'i' ■*♦' ^ 


n^  N^  -^  ^  os^  ■^'^  ■^ 


^s.rtsi5^tov 


M^  (ov  cN  aj^  id^  e*^  ^  ici^  c5n -^ 


s?  s;sJ;s 


w^  e3s  1-^  ^  ^  otN  «^  ^  «4^ 


•^  ^  >^  >^  vW  i^  ^  >^*r4  >w 
OTv  w^  c^ -^  ciTs  e*s  pj^  c^  co^  w^ 


OS    Gi    '-    ^ 


nW  vPi  ^  *>e>l  vTJ  NP5  Nf3  ><0  sC*  ■'fS  ""f^  ^^  vC-l  >£1  v«  N( 


vfj  N^  ^r*  ^  ^f*  >P5  ^  >^  ^ 


aoo^a»>o<o«cc-Hoo     oo  t^  o> 'f  o>  o  ^  >o 
ep ci >-i t^  f-i ec >d t^ tv -^      epu3Q^»oo»0'^ 

^  ^  ^^  •<44  lO  to  ^  ^  U5  O         N         lOCSCOCOMCO 


TfJ o6 -H r-1 00 00 1-<    ldcot~^^ 
rt  rt  M  rH  i-H  t-(  N     icoeo       ■* 


.-i.-iooO'H.-ic>jot 


mSi 


>  a>  o  o>  a>  r~  00 


^  00 -^  »C  »C  OS  CO  »0 -^  CO        CI  »0  CO  CO  *o  t^  «  OS 

^co>6c^c4>o'o6cjr>^c^      co^o^tct^oow 

■^  CO  "-H  •»  "O  «  CO  •>».  ICO         C^t-HCO^CO         r-iN 


05«ONM«ococo»or*»o»o-^ 

»o^c^'^os»oc*iaao'<i5c»jeo 
.1 64 -H  i-H  — .  IN  !n  PS  CO      c5 


i-c      eo-<>< 


c>)iOtacococoao>oeoC40iaoc^ 
--      e^csCT'O'O'Tj'M'^e^'-Hio 


'Ji  «>  rt  lO  to  (>•  00 -^  M  >o      >o  M  o>  t- o  t~  t^  OS 
ci  o>  t«^  »-^  t>^  *d  Q  CO  »d  o      ^  ooosoi  cooo  »o 

lO  T}' p^  to  «a  CO  *C  iO  CO  ^    CO  ^  »0  C4  CO  CO  CO  CO 


■"J-OO—ICOOOCOOCOCOIOOOCO 

Oso6-Ht^oo6eoc6cooot^op 
•-H  «  N  .-I  CO -H  e^  CO  CO  CO      ^ 


CO  00  OS 


00>OCOOOC40S'<<0S 
OQCOt^eO'^'^OCJQ 

e<iioiouioidco^co 


"J"  CO  CD  ■«(<  t»  t^  00  "-H  N  lo     OS  c»  o  00 'J' t~  r»  CO 
oi  as.eo  Qt^ioQco>dQ     cio6-^oocoo6t>^ 

»0  ^  "CS  »0  iO  CD  >0  u5  CO  »        CO  i-<  »0  CO  ^  CO  CO  CO 


OS-^OOCOt^uSt^MCDCOOOO 

Osd*ot^i-io»ooscoo6t*^b^ 


.  t-HdrtCOpjCJCOCOCO 


o  coooo 
^  o6t^T(< 
e4     co>oco 


00t^C0OOC0C0i-<0> 

SioSusSSeooS 


OOOSOC^C^CO^OOIOOO 

t-^cicDoscd—irjSoococi 
coco-^comcocortoio 


O  CJ  -H  O  "O  00 -"T 

CO  OS  00  ^  CO  CO  o 


ot^-os-HMcoe^ooooN-^co 
■ooco>oo6'>a-'*oscococ>i« 

CO  «  i-H  .-<  .-H  M  fl  ■*  CO         !-• 


OOOOOOM'OOO'O'M—IOOSCOCO 

oocscipscd*oco»oot^cot^o6 


CO  0>  O  ■V*  «0  ■*  CO  CO  "O        COOS4<CDCOOOCS 

OS  ^^  •«<  r- >o  CT  »~  OS  CO  CO      co  co  •*  co  "O  i-h  ^  t»< 


rH<V)  —.  rt 


OS  CO  CO  c<  c^jii  >a  CO  ^t^o  co  >o 

^  OS  CO  t-^  Ci  00  CO  ^  pH  CD     'os 
^^  ^  WCO  »-<  ^CO«5  »0        CO 


«OC000t~C0"9<OC>»00OTt<^00 

TaJt^^c4o5eoot^i^QC4c4c^ 

(^■*^ocD'*'0-*-<o<«Tj<eMt- 


t^0»0  00  CS  00  ^  t^OS  CO        CO  CD  Tf  t^  OS  1^  ^  t^ 

ci  OS  ci  OS  r^  CD  CO  CO  OS  CO      o_il'-^os  OQcso 

I0'9*i^'^^-^i0*0»0»0         CO    I    COM -^^^  CO 


COCOCDCDtJ'OCO'^ 

of4o6e4e4>ooocOi-<cbot^ 


CO  Cl  >-< '-' CJ  «  >-<  CO  «  CO        "S"        i-H        CO  ■»»<  M '-"^  ■«•  "O  ■*  O) 


^t^t^OSOOCOOOt^COOSf-HCON 
o6cDI>^'*o6o>'"00«Q'H2'lO 


>-<as  oososoe -^w      CO  N  e>)  t>.  >o  CD  CD  lo 

SClCOrt  CO  C»  NCOCO         «N«^.-c 


■-■  t~  CO -H  M  C»  CO  ^  O  M  "I  N       «o      C«t~cD       copoosRooc^cocot; 

C4*M  rHCO"— »'CSi-HCN»-H»-Hf^CO 


t^  CO -^no  »o  »o  QO  t^  r^  00         1  OB  lo  ^ 'J*  c^  sp  CO 
<oScoast~o>2<oeooo         <cicO'^c^ciFi^ 


oco^ooajt^r-^t^Nt-cD 


lO      f-i  OS  r^  CI  ^  ^ '-I  OS  OS  CO  t*  00  c« 

f-t   OS  00  C4  •-<  C4  OS  OS  lO  CO  CO  CO  CO  OS 


xj  2  ^ 


CO  M      ■      . 
Of  OS  CO  CO 


m  S'w  fcl  •-     I  T;  ^  £  "a  ISO.S  O  ■- w  M     'i'O 

i:  o5a  o-  S  ^  o S^  oj  03  "  a!  =55  «  « 


i-S 


1^ 


'~  «  o  aj 


bo 

a 
=3   . 

:3  0) 

3S3 


a  ^' 


IZW 


-o  i-Bxi'"  a"  01  o  K  ot§^  ^  .  Mo  "-S  £  "i^rt-S-S  i 
S  0  0  ci>  g>^  S-3  o:2<g3;i^  -c  ^2^  S  D.3  3  a  a  a^' 
»'oo.!3SSS=£5oo^aoSo^«x5>.ooa»«'3 


«  -o 


^>H    a 

"^  -4-1 


SO -2  CJ  CO -2  >0  CO  b- OO        OS  Q -"  C<  CO  ■<><  >0  CO 
__opooooooooooooooor      —^ 


S  OS  OS  OS  OS  OS  OS 


r^  00  OS  o  ^  N  CO  Tj*  *o  CO  t*  00      os      o  i-^  ci  co -^  "O  co  t^  oo  os  o  *-«  ci    ^ 
o:  asasooC''Oooooo     o  .  r-i^H^^»-<^H^^f-t^H,-i,-ic4c*c»    cw 

•^•^T)-i0»0>O«5«0i0i0»0»0        ^         JOWSiOiOiOiOtOiOurjlOiOiOiO 


182 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


NtO       ONO  •«»<       ■<<  <o  <0 -VO  ■«  to -^  <0       OOOOCCtON       to 

t^*ri^aiuio6       OOOOOOOC^Ot^OOQ6cOQOQ-^QcDciot*OU?t^»O^OeO 
COIN      ?>o  e<5      M  —I      n^i-h3      >o      r~  00  e5  to  Tti  t- 


M  «  M  i-H  CO  "5        wCO  T.-' 


^CT  N  ^_^  V  CO  ,__«0  Tf«<Ci-IC0t-O00Mt»>O00r"O>^©^ 


uT^  uj-.  cj^  cr .  (3\  IT 


e5^ilTsc^c5Ne5NNS<SNi^«0"  d^^^e^'^v^^^pjvco^c^o^w^iflNO^'a^tJ^^^o'^^MNr^s 


s  irtv  "^  u5v  c5^  iJ^ 


i3^  i2^  wv  i3^  cSn  »2k  c^ '^  e^N  «N  w^  CT^  e5^  e*^  NN  <5^  c5n 


«;:?;;;?j: 


OOOOsrooo 


«  ■*  TO  CO  ■W*         rt         IM  1 


00 1^  oa  o  "O  to  00  >o      r^^owo      ■*  i-h  « t- -h  to  "«"  to  c«i  to  to  « to  eo 

t^tDTO06<O< 


l28+'*®S28:f°°='S^S§Sg'°g?SS§Sg;5«"* 


iC  OS  00  N  tfi  -Tj* 
1^  ^  QO  >C  CO  -^ 

cococ^Sco  ^-^ 


000i00C^CDCD0000t>-00(N.t^00Tt<O»OO^t*00NOW»0wCS03O00 


rnWeO        CO         lO-^CSCD<D 


CO  o  -^  r^  •-<  o 


-^  -^  CO  o«  •-<  »o 
^■^co-^io^ 


COiOCOW»CCOOOO'*t^»OOOOOiOOOOOC^OOOOOt^'^Oi"<*'«D'^ 

r-loicbcse6o4li-HT|J'^coQ"^oCt^o6*6oo>'^t^OQOco«^OTjJco«-5 


lo  '•I*  o  oi  --H  »o 


^»ooocoo5'^oO'^eor»?oocooOrHWeooc^ooooeot>»^t*^«oeo 
»^o>oQ»cosc^ilcoco'^'^oc^oaoico^QoJ^oscioseo^o^coic5 
w      c5  w  r-( 2^ "T CNi     i5 ^ «  eoco^^-^     t^iocor^t^co      ih 


(DOS  CO  QO  coo 

00  OOQ  Tt<  CC  CD 
CO  CO  C5  CO  -v^ 


eot>-*ococoM*oooocsb-coec)ooooot^ooicocor*oO'<*»Ma»cot>-t^co 
o6c4i^'-HiM^  i'eoi>o6^  i*i-Jo6t-Ho6-^ooi'^cD--3cst^i-HQ<DcooJ 


C5  t*  CD  t^  «-<< 


CO  CO  ^  Oi  Oi  CO  t-»   W  i-i  C^   t>- CO  t*   t*  CO  •-<  1-H  OJ  b*  C^  00  »C  W3  03 -^  iO 
idC^OSCDcdc^i-HOo6t^COO*O^CDO"^>'^Oc5t^CS»0^05o6'«4?COt^»0 

cocD'-ir»   coo  CO  rococo   *-i 


N   CO  W  WCO  I    i-H^ 


i-H  CO  O  t^  *0  -^  <-i 

OS  00  O -^  lO  »0  OS 
CO  CO  "^  CO  CO  ^  CO 


OCOC^t-»»OW   CD    O   CO   00000"^'-*0»'-<COCO'^WC^<NOS    1-H 

c^oaioo6oocDoc6ot^o^'-H»0'-^o6osc4'<5*'^'-5o6coQcoof«- 

M-Hf^lCS'-tCS    C4    CO    C4    »-4.-lCSWCO«-l^f-HtiiCOCOCO00«-<    rH 


COOC^OQ'*  W 

rH  ^   c5co 


•«**oooow«-*0'^^HOOs»o<o»ooo-^oow:iwcC'OOcoosoiOii-t»o 
>  C<  ^Hi— tcswcococococo 


0>C«OSCOCO<N        iOC^OOCOcDN<-(CCiO'^tN.OCO^piO>^»OCOCO*CWb»M*r^»0»-<0 
coco         t^COC^  1-4  i-H  .-(  ■^         — •  -H         W  M  N  CD  »-H  CO        00  0>  i-i  OS  00  Oi         i-t 


o)  H  a) 


.9-S-9 


a '3 .2 
sag 

,— •  03  <D  S  O  ? 


,  ®  fl  o  © 


„=;  a  aT3  S-S  5'S  S-s-y  "  g  §  i^-S  '='t^  3  n  a  ti  t-^  9'?,5 

g(Uoo»S.®>>02aoO.2a!3oeijpaJE;ja-a-"O®r 


H  o 


3.Sg 
d:^  2 


"So 


CO-^u^COr^OOOS         Oi-iC^C0'^M5CDr-000SO'-'C^C0'V>CCCi^000SO^C^C0'^>CC0t^00 

CMC^c^MNCNiw       coc5cocoeocoeocococo^'^'^-^'^-gC'^'^^'$*o»cio»o»o»o«o*o»2 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


183 


OBtoMNoooo     no     o     C40 
ooooooeoo>oca>t-^r-<o>dgdoQOOe<s 


'  0000       C«CO        -VO       OC4C«  C4  <«• 

•ooot-iNoggjoggogoocgooo^jooogo 


^^CO  *0  CO  CC  »0  t^  >0  O  CO  lO  <D  »0  CD  00  ^^iM  ^^CM  O 

J^«o  ^  ^  rJ  fh  00  c(5 1-*    '    'oJcieo^^ciC-cd^ 

eo  W  ^_^<0  CO  CO  CD  O  >0  00  t-H  O       OCOOOOO*^        ^       b^CDiOOt 

eo  lo  wco  ci  N  o  -^  »o  ci  CO  t^  wcd  od  co  -^  .-J  wco  w(^  r^  ^  ^ 

■sp  rt  ^^  nW  NTS  NfS  ^«o  >» -^  Nfo  >«o  %«  s«  srt  N«  N«  ^«  xra  >f>  >*^ 

t«aocoaoaoKoeaoh>»ooooao«eeaoaoeooh-t<.eo« 

ofl^  cl^  «r^  eis  ^  5^  V^ -Ss  ^  .^fs  iiji^  e^  e^  tX  ^  t^N  ^  c^  ^  cN 

e^  Mjv  c4s  cK  e4^  p*^  e^  c*v  ris  e^  e*^  ,>s  ds  ^  e*v  ^  (5^.  e*s  (^  ^  d^  «*v  c^ 

e^  Ns  oy^  aS^  «"' 5^  tcf^  wN  >-N  r-K -Is  (cJs.  c3n  o5«>  c<^  r^ 

'>*t0  0«0'^  t^OOC>OOOOOOOOOC403kOCDO^ 

<CMcooaco'>ot-^N->a».-<>doo«)«;t>^co<ot^eo 

r~<»»Mooa>i-ii-(oooi-<'00>oocomooeo-«<co 
tDo6"ctd'0>ot~^«oc4o6Ni<'«<'-<'-<?4(NT(;    'oJ 

r-l      r  M  i-<l-l_l_C».-H  l-H  rt  rt  1-1  i-H  e^  ,-1  CO  N 

CO     i-iiO'*t~t^oooNos<oa5U5ooo<3>ocon< 
eoocoo&o>>do6^t^^cDt>^>OiOC>odcdc»csco 

C>5        i-lNilr-r    I    ■♦.-l-HTHi^         N  eC  CO  i-H  CO  «  CO 

eo     ^iooocot~oco<ot~eoa>o<oooo^>-i  ^ 
cooe>5'i)"«ocoodTiiod^t-^tdidt-^e^oood'd--c5 

t^        CD  00  t^  r^  1^  O  CO  00  00  00  CD  O  ^  O  CO  00  C*3  CO 

to  CO  »0  t>^  lO  wi  CO  CO  C<  t^  1-i  CO  O  CO  CO  00  CO  CO      'OS 
l-l       .  M-HW      iNl-C  rt  rn  «  fH  r-H-H  1-1  CO  C5 

00  I  I 

I ' 

o»     c>cocDc>)>-c«^NC»«o>ot^caooo»N>-i 
oioocd^co-^coo6o>t^co»6o6'*wt>»dc6i^ 

■<4*         ^  CO  ""ij*  CO  r-*  t^  f-<         i-(  CO  W  ^  t^  NN  O         -^ 

I 

t-c^t^rt  O'OioooioooscoO'^coocoo     o 

CDt^cdoO'^^»OCO^^r^r-^QCDCOQCO»0005 

—  j.—  cSc'iN      CO -H .I —I N 00 rt -H  B      CO      N 

OP»cS'-<'-i'Hcot^'>j<'«'Ocococo-^o>oocooo 
eococo  cS  w      CO 


lOO  toco     o     e<5  CO  l-l  CO  CO  CO  CO  00  l-l  CO  "O  ■*  eo  00 

eo'oooOr;t^02®*^K*eoidcd'<«<  X*^'  ei  es  ei  •*  co  o 
•IN  iOi-i      eo  «      Jlj_j_-<T     j_.-i  i-i  « .-I 


•<*  w      N      t-i 
r-;  ci  o  •-;  o  CO 


ococ^r>i-icococo^i-iov>ocoi-ico 
jco»oc6»coe»5eo 

+++++++ 


WCO  '»'CO        00       000-<COT»<OOt»e»OCOlON^O» 

rcs5©ooe3t--'o-HONcDoiX5^'^«coodcie4M06e<io 

N  CS  »0  iH        ^        «^N  IN  i-lf^»-lcON 


•-ICO      N      veo      00  rt  00  CO  ■-<  eo  CO  N  i-i  r~  lo  n  i^  o» 

!g350c4oe2«^o-<coiocDos_Lodoocoo>t>;pie<50S<o 


I  to      CM      o 

<  i-i  o  -H  o  ■* 


>o«ooo>tooco«oooooo«ocoo>oo 


«(ic»     CO     «         t^  •<«' CO  to  o  o  a»     eo  «o  CD  N  eo  o  >o  t" 
idgo^O'Oooootog'dooioioO'^copi'H-voseicoo 


■-<•-!  ooot-^^oo>oo6cDooocooo6o>eocico'*io'o 

CON  ^<0        eo         rtCOi-li-l         _1_  1-1  i-l  N -Jl  rH 


COt^OCOtOION^CD^kOOOONOOOOeO^^OeOOtOUdCON 


cocoosft^ooiecoeOTtiTfeooot-i-icD^NJ^ 


coeOT(iTf<eooot-i-ico^N«^N 

1-1  1-1  CO  11  i-l         CO'*'         i-lil         N 


1-l^^OCOiAN      I  ^1-1  ^OSOO^OOt^  CO  t^t^  •*  ^-^O  »0  COC^ 


■^       I         iji         ^  N         rH  ^H  i-l 


S'*'2SS?' 


Ifc-r.fe 


ill 


irC^o-S-S-o 


fe  ■<  t,  ^  Q  Q  ^  fLi  ^  O  cy  w  m  Ph  P-i  CO  m  CO  ^  c 


•O  00  o  - 


0?  a)  a> 
.■"•WO 

fc  °  $ 


fulfil  t.ri|liil§ls^li 


5gS 


N  00 

aa 

S  oJ'o'o'S 

Port's  "a 
mfQouu 


>  4Q  to  O  U2  tC  t 


co'^iccor^ooosOi-»c^co'«j«*r5cph*oo^Q»^c^cO'**<»ocDi^ 

SOOOOOOCpODQQOiOiCsOiOSOCTOSOOlQOQQOQQO 


247140 — 41 — No.  1- 


-14 


184 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


o  oo«coTt*tocDdWTfTfooo"^  -^roco      -^C^      OCOOO      OOO      ■^'^CO 

M  -^C^         C<l  05  »0  CO  CO  .-t  CO  ^  »0  C5^0i        coo  i-t  iH(0^         «^»o 


'<rt<0605«OOCO(NOiC^C^OO»C»OcO(C''*COOCOOCOOO>OTt<C^OOC<l 

wo^^co^'"^cs^o^Dr^TJ5c^'cou^cDa>w^c^»o^'^lO»oco^^'-HC<^ 


i-i  CO  CO  i-H  C4  C<i  Oi  w  CO  »o  fO 


c^  C«*N  c4s  c^  cfv  ^  ^x  c«Js  c^  c 


;;j;2;: 


■^cjNr>,c«r,t^e4"  cT^a>^  ot^-^K^j^ 


■NC^^*.-^^tf4Nrt^^.xay^-^e^lrt^oJ^^is,-^os^.ofve^cNO'■e^CJ^CN^^  e^^ere^ar  M^       p^.-<jK.-Kt^c^(Os**v;^fflNcr  CK 


d^>'3^c5'  5s.i-K»5^  Ol  ^  «rt^  "l*^  c5"- MN 


^Oi-iFHt^wot^osoc; 


o  «o o CO -^ CO  CO -^ -^ o OS  t^  r* -^  cx> CO  1-1      ■*      -^eocooi 

^'*'"  -"  ^.^i?5?D         rHCOCOeiCOC^CO^COl 


^         -^OINCO 


+     +  + 


+" 


—  —  I  1       <o^co>o 


•  u^r^os  —  oscjw-v^c^ 


■-1         -"Ji  IM  —KM  "-H 


r-  loocc  Tj<o  CO ''j'co  ^  t^r*  00000030  t^M      ^os^co 

?)  — 1  lib N M  M c-S  — I      lo      ^      -H      -M  r~cjtDco 


cico>0i-i0osoor~-^'- o 


eONco-<**oo^p>cciiocOTT* 
c<coc<5nconm-hcc^_»o 


•O  O  M  00  CO   JO  ■<»HD  ^  CO  t>- t^  CO  00  CT>  O  r~  Cq         ■*05'J"tO 

oooooicJ>ofi^ocO'-<od"-<-^"5coocoo<Oi-IoNe~i'<j'C 


NOOt-COOOWOOt^  —  — iC 

^'toco^or^^oseDOco'  " 

— •)  M  c-        — 


t>-<N«6tO        C^  CO  CC  C^  CO  M  CO  ^  ■<»" 


+-'= 


f-H   'f       OS  O  ^ -^  f- Oi  00  »0  lO  O  N  <D  CS  C<»  CO  to   CO   O  O  CO  00 

-^o    'ocdad'<fosioi>^r^o6'^cscsioc^'»di-Ieo      "^'o^'c^'od'^ 

^         ■^  i-H  ^  C^  Cv|  Tj*  I  O     I  CO'-'oi-^ 


ocowoO'^c^cor-^*-o 
o>  Q  c^'  05  (^  »o  05  ^  t~^  r-^  CO 


CO      1-t      r- w  Tj*  00  w  CO  i-Hio  o  QO  OS -^  r^  o      —"co  ocot-oo 

odotoocooioc^^r^'-«'-^c^'r^osiocdt^o^T^oo^»--'*oco 
*'      —        -tc^ioocoeo      b-      <-i  ft  cDi-Hcocc 


^(N   I 


i:^oo»cooco»ot^oaio  — 

ocot^coooooooQiidr; 
•-ic^ooc»-'*<i-'Ccc5^   1  oc 


O  CD  O  b- 00 -^  C^  CS  CO  t^  *-"  CO  O  OS  lO  b*  1-1  Tt«        ^OOSi-t 


OOOOOb»QC0CDC0C^0SC^'^»-<C0'^00b-'-ib*'^Ot^»OC0'^ 
CO         »OC^COCCC^         rH  lO  ^-t  »-i     I  _L_j I  CDCSTfCO 


+ 


o—ic^c^coc^eDTrf^oa* 
r^ooooCM'ao-^  — i-^'^'-rKi 

CO  ■«"        CO  CO  CO  T(>         ■<)<  _1    M 


MT)<c01M'«><I^T»><0tD0»T(<tDC000<0  0f'C0C0-HiOC0t^^OIM00T)>        00'OC^CI'rcD-*C'*'<3- 
CS— irt—c  "^COC-ICO  — lt->"COC^  — 


CO -"jtt^  Noo  w  «?o '^ -^  eD«og>coos  c^os  COCO  «or^  ^cooo  »OGO      ^ 


OC^^^UOCIOOIOC^OOO 

■vc<esoO'>J<^      ■»      ■^ 


I'll 


O   03.2  g 


■i^fsg^.s 


o  o  o  o  o  £.  o  o  t^.S  03  3r3r3 
o  o  o  r:>  ri  n  ti,  J  ■^  n .  r-i  <-vJ5  JB 


3-0  3 
5  o  >? 

2WO 


lis 

a  o'S 


a  §5 

(3  to  — 


0)  k,  03  01  dflx: 
E-OUOUOO 


:—  «  - 

>  O  w  D 
05  g  JJ 


"2  » 


SSS^r^^^^'^^'^oo^©— *c^cO"^»oor*ooc»o^c^ico-^      »cot^ooa>o— 'C^co'«S'»c 
S?s^Sr:ir^r^r:i':i':;':i'^^'^^^'M*Mc^c4c5ficococococo     cococococo-^-^j'-'t^vTf-j* 

cocc>CDCOCOeOCOCOeOCD<0«DeO^<OCDCDCOCOCC>OC05D50;D<OeD       eo^ooccoto'^^to^so 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


185 


^_^  to  ^_^  rH -^  ^  CO  ^^  <0  WD 

£-*  £n  »d  t^  ^  £06  N 

ci  »o  c«  ci  ^  ^'  ^*  M  CO  0 

t^t-tQOCO^^^^t^C^lOO«Dt^OO-^^        00  00  M  CO -^O 

^  ^  oi  06  w^i^  coco-^odcood-Hrs:  ;^(o  r<I  ^  c^  c4  co 

oe«ooaoao«coto«eo 
MS  e5^  «P  wS  eVs  ^  cK  ^  ifls  c3n 

tfs.  tJv  cK  ^  »5v  ejs  cjs  e5^  rts  Jn 

00    K 

r^aDt^«aoaot^wr«oocDcooo«aoaor<'t<>ot*t-ao 
^v  ^^  .>K  c^  ejs  eJv  p^  e4v  .-K  crs  (0S.  cTv  c^  oK  ejs  e^v  .^K  ^  .^  Qffs  rX  <ff\ 

Ks  ^  ^  e^  e5^  e^  cK  0?^  t§^  t5v 

^^ 

-aK  ws  ■^^  .«j^,  OT^  e^  ©  V  ^  co^  u3^  idv  rtx  uT^  tJ^  offv  c^  <->v --i^  r^  wv  f-*^^ 

|.I;?|^;I;S^^;§ 

■spiNrO's«v«Nr5NfON«N^sr4>^ 
e^  M5^  0*^  etv  CIV  or*  cK  ^  u?^  ^ 

oooMotet^o>o>j-ico 


lOCON  i-l  r-l  M  CO  (^ 

+         ++ 


am 

Sis 


^CO00CO»O      '  uD  ^^  00  10  1-1  t^  O '<*' OS  "^  O '«»' W3  O  OC  O 


?S?^S;^  iSsSS^Si^SSS^SSSSSS 


«5n    "«o^'oO'*'_l1co  >d 


t^t^f-i>aioncoo^c4oa>i-it~^^oo<-io3e4co 

oi  t-^  CO  o  -^  _iloo  •--c^c5iS«5»dc5i-H<o?pw?»o»o»-5^ 
cocococo      Tc!ic^c»-«c^  o5«f5i-i      Pi f5 t-c eo co ■-■ 


ClT)<iO<C100rHt-NC000 

t^(^rHidoi^cdc4co^' 
io-*-^i-ic«eo^cocot>- 


rgcio5r^'^'<rgoe4^c4^coooo>cd«d^c>i<d»oo>oi 

■«"»>COCO  Si  C^  M -H  CO  CO  •-<  CO  1-1        CO  CO  ^  CO  CO  i-l 


r-)Oit-i->tDMO'>'NOO 

ooocoorJoico'piao 
)«eoi-i 


■—11-1      eoco< 


oio>ocoa>a>^«oi-i(x> 

.00  OJ  -H  00  ■-<  Ci  00  CO  «  -"li 


r)  o 


c4C4c4r«iciooi-^>0'4*i-Hi4<i-HO)03U3i-Ht^a»cooci 

f^coco  CO  Pi «  1-1  fi  CO  i-i  ■*  r-i      CO  CO  »-i  Tj<  ^  rH 


tee^-i)iooeoNNcqoo 

—  O)  I     r-.  i-l     I 


b-ooc^toiocoeoNc^oo 
ocop'»Oi-icOi-ioat>^co 

COC0«  rt  1-1        1-1  to 


C^-^OJb-t^COi-iOOCSUSW'^'^C^OOONtO'^OO'^O 


— <■  Q  in  h^  .-■  ~<  a>  10  oj  ci 

1«»*  C««l        «    I 


ooo>oop»ootooo«ot~ 

S'^Dcociodoodod^ift 
l^  CO  CO  ^  Co        t^^  Oi 


003 

N?5 


t^OOCOO^        OC^  OOSQO^  CDt^  t^COCOOOt^OO 

*r3as'^^030ioirit^»o«5coi-ioooo6oO'-Ht^o*-< 
ot»r^ic  -^ -^ -^      »-i  CO  CO  »o  coco^ooio^ 


:i.-5  0CO6t~eO        oooc^ 
j«j     ■fii-I«DOO'^I>^ 


il<CO       ^  O —I  to  •*  t^  <3> 


fojoi-i      o  r- CO  00  «i  t~  1-1  h- 1-1  cj -H  <o  >o  M  00  o  <e 

io»oio^O'^g5o6»OTi<cd|>»oco»oc^'^coa5oi'^iO 
■a-eoco'j'  c5  i-c  1-1  rt  CO  N 1-1  CO  o3 "  CM  c-5 1-1  Pi  ■*  c4 


=  aeococoNC40coa> 


?32 


>o  r- >a  >o  CO  CO  Til  >o  00      toci 

CO  ^-H  1-1  « 


i^co«cooo-<i-ieoN'fl<Ncoi-ic»0'0'>i'e<"5^eo 


e> o 'V  t> ?)  >o t~ CO  to     oaooo>o;oooeor» 


—  OO-H  ,-1  (K<  ^  _l  ,-1  pH 


oo>o;oooe 
«      1-1      -^3e 


-Hioiocooc^r^coa3c^o»co^^t^xc^t»t«t^t»coo 


OS 


a  ;.2s  o 


S 


sg 


§»Sao2-S 


si  |-o|l  ill i|  aS-il  S  -a|! 
I|lt||f||||l§|-i|||||sl 

Ul  ^ 


«2 
boo 


!8& 

»  ®  b  „    , 


3-^ 

•g  _a  03  ft  u,   ■ 


i-SflSS  33.2.2.22 


00 


.So-; 


a3o32!3'at;^Si^i^aBa)a>».S- 

mmooM<(a5^fefeh:ii-qwwwoooPH(iiM   a 


^iJ~^  fe    •!-> 


-*^i  I 


:|3? 


SiO  kO  kO  kO  10  to   ic  to  u5  to  c 
CD  CO  ^  CD  CO  CD   CD  CD  CD  CO  c 


*  N  CO  -^  *o   y  t) 
7  CD  CD  CO  CO   CO  r>- 

3  CO  CD  CO  X)    CO  CO 

-O  CO 


cjco'Vtocor^ooo»Oi-<Mco'^*ocot^c 


t*t~»t^t^t^r>-r>-t^aoooooooooo6ooooo6oOOTaaoi  _- 

CO  ;OCOCOCOCOCOCOCOCOCDCDCDCDCDCDOCDCOCO<OCO 


186 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


CO  i-l  CO  CS  N 


r- <o  oa  "5  00 -^  cc  r^  cc      -^  co  o  as  t^  o  go 


1-1      ^  N 


>Or*00»C5Dt'-OSOS'-HOiCOiO 
CO     *      '      '      '^CO     'r-J     "r^ci 


^  f5v  i2s  ^  ^IN  eJ^  ^^,  tO\  ^f .  e5 .  c-l^  e*N  c^^  c^- OTv  c*^  N-v 


o(^lCf^r^^evH^.»c^o(^4'^CJ^o>"^o>Nc5^eJv<l^olv^Js^is,      l5^tf)N(tfslJvl5^a^•cy^t-^^-^^^>K^«^ 


>ri  sct  sTi  v-M  sr>  vc-i  Nfj  ^i  s?»  ^  >r5  -^ 
O^  «T^  e>r^  c^  *o^  c*v.  cN  (tfs  c4"  iff^  oOn  iQS. 


tOy,i>^,-Kc5--ttf^W^tf"^^ 


<ooos'«**»^co»oco—<T-<r-«i-ic<)eocDeo 

t>o6QQ<d"^CDCSo6oic6o>05Tt'OiCCD 
WT*<PS.-<CSl<-HCOrt         ^  C^COi-HCO 


COt^-'J^eOC^kO^Di-HCOC^Q'^ 

.-H  c^  c^  c5  CO  CO      j_     _j_c5ci 


»OCOOOOOO^«OW3 


^  w  d  ^  fl  w ,-( ,-t 


-«j«  M  est-- Qot^t--ai»oi-Host-"^cDo  coos 


.-iM^i-'i^i-ii-HCSr-l  t-t     I IM  CO         I-* 


<0*Or^O0000CM»O0aO'^CD 

P  K  ri  ^  ^  ^ '^  X*^  ""^   '^ 


oio-^-^t^attcscs 


O  cc  r-4  CO  «o  lo  b-   I  q 

i-H  C5  CS  f-H  W  CO         T^ 


CDCS-^OCOCOO^^ 


0«0«f-H-^'*'*<<D'<*<CS«OCMCS»-iCO«OCO 

cot^coo><oi-'5eccso6od*rfosoi'^Qd»r3«D 
»-<  N ''t*  M  .-•  cs  .-H  CO  i-H  <-i  1-t  c^co^co 


000^0»wt^«Dt^»OOS^«0 

03  t- ^ -^  CS  00  00  jl<o  X"-*  "^ 
^Ncscscoco      "T     Treses 


»0  O  t^  00 1-- o  o>  •* 


0(OOi<-*'^c^t*a>eocscDt^<DooocDeo 
o6t>op5^t^^^f^c^oo*ovco<cotocd 

.-iCS^cii-iCS.-HCOCS^i-Hi-<i-HMTjii-HCO 


r^OOi-Ht^lCOeOOOttiOSrHO 


S'  CO  o  t^  go  CO  ^  CO 
M  e^  .-1  fS  eq  e<<  .-c 


MOO 
T-t  2^  CO 


0000O01'*OC^1iOt1<1N 

N  r*  -H  i-i  I    I  e-i  CO      <-! 


OJ>OOOCOlOMiOCOOOC<500eoe<«0<Mi-iCl 

g"-^e^cO'oa;o6(Ncqc5<0'<><"0'S'oo<3 
O  t^  "*         Ci         ITD  UO  c5  CO  tH  1-H  »0  OO     1 


•ooo>coOM'c»oco'*oO(Ne-) 
cocctjKcscot^^'-Hcoc^oogo 


»O^CDod»O^OW 

cocoeo   c-)co(N  1-1 


00  ■-<  O  CO  ■*  M  "3  ■*  O      t~  t~  t>. -^  t- ■* 

t^-njI-^CO^CDCOCOOOOOcdcDCOOQOiT-^ 
»-H  CO  W3  C^  CO  CO  CS  CO        ^^  i-i  »-i  oi  c^  uo 


0>'^O'^*O00C00iCD»O'«J«^ 

cvicocS(>io-^os»-<-<}*^ict^ 
c^coeoco^co  MW 


NCOCOO'Ot-OOO 

c*if-^ocbot^t>cD 


ICO  r-l  oco  ^ -^  coooc*  ^       -^  00  »o «-' 00  ^  CO -^  cq  CO  w  »o 


'j'meoxsooi-HO 


■^■^eo    '  ■*    '    I »-<  1-t CO r^ lo »o CO Q 00 00 


S    Is 


si 


■o.§S 

a  CO  c3 

<DS3   05 


Ob-     , 
„  OS  osSs 


cj  SX3  o  >  m  bixl 

^  0  H  5  S 


ppooC-woooS 


"        O  o  ^ 

..Hfloia'ro.'r, 
a  ajajacfl  a  S  a  ' 


□  «iw$«'2g3jag-3'S£e«ii<nSggj3jai:£iagH« 


m  ctl  <V 

"  o  ^ 


■2° 


>«io«r^aoc»o^P'^io<pt^oo^O"-t      csco'^io<ot>.oooiO'-icsco*^>«ot^goosO'-<c<i 
5tt^o>oa500^ooooooi-'»-i      ^— <i-»^i—i-H^i-Hf5cscscsic'icscsc4p5c5coeoco 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


187 


271.2 

346.8 

64.6 

306.4 

jj'  t~  »■  o  o  o  2  -i^'  o  2  2 

00 

C»        00       M             O        NOOOOCJ       ON        O 

-<ooo-HOo>oO'-'''ooosoi»<e>50o5o 

CO         •-*                                        »-*  00  CO  o 

8®  i 

o-vco 

CC  OOCO  lO 

t~aooo«ONoO'«'0»>oo 

o> 

>0  00  CO  CO  0>  ^^CO  >0  ^^Cq  CO  «  CC  O  •<»<  00  »  o  ___ 

»     ' 

•"jieon) 

t»(3»«00 

■*w*00'»"<O'*e<iNNus 

>o 

■w'-HW'*     Z^-^  t^^ci  n  ei  ei 'tf  e6  m  CO  <6Z^ 

<di.   1 

00  00  r«  r»  r«  I 


dKc5^o^       ^JJC^+v^      3^^3^dKc5N<-fMrrN«^tf^CT^-5\       e5s       eQ^eV>e^d^cNe^^o^eQ^«^^c4^M^cT^e3^r^ 


H^ 

1^1^ 

« 

:K^ 

a>  »  9 

0»   9    9    Ok 

J^  «dv  .d^  w^-^  CN  e^  <rfs  c5s  c5^  ^v 

^ 

MI^OO 

0>0'<«*00 

Ot-*0C^0&00        CCt>.-HCC> 

00 

Tfi->i<i-io>coeooc»oco.-io«oo«oe>r->-ii-i 

^^ 

S?3S 

00— too^ 

coNcoecr-^H      '^■^ccco 

s 

^  to  id  rr  CO  OS  00  ci  oi  OS  lo  uJ  e4  Q  CO  •-'  »■  "5  uj 

1— 1  f-H 

"  + 

■^c^oos     r*  t*  00  — ^  CO  >o  ^  OS -^  c^  c^ 
pi  -h'  t-:  •*      id  o  ci  "d  CO  to    '  to  id  <N  -w 

-.        -)  .^  (M  « 


0>00C00SO'*C^O'-"'("0bO->1<0SrtC0e^5DW0SNi000 


Mcqso      tococoto      eococoN      o»      cO" 


QC^^CO— ^C<IOaiOCO— ^■^tOiOOSlOOt^COlO'^t^r-iCO 
f5_|_'H^^  I lUOC^COMPj  «C<-HriN  J_-*i-l+<«< 


ososioi-t      tot^t^wio-^      t^^eoo 

idcOOioO        -"jil^COOCOOOONtOCO'tD' 

r.t^'Vr.      >*cocOcoe^e5      if'j'coco 


"TTC^t-eoooooiotocoosoot^oot^oo 


00    Tj;  Q  to  00  CO  .-t  CO  t*  OS  GO  O  »0  lO  O  lO  lO  OS  h»  lO 

00     ciN^^i-irtM      lo  3  3  CO  lO  « ■*  CO  1-1 «  Jl 


•-C0O 


coot~- 

t~;o  to 


OOIO  lO  OS 

CD  id  o>  00 


CO  ^  CO        t^  t^  ^  t^ 


i-iiOC<t~tOt^Tl<OS 
CO  CO  lO        OS  OS  t^~  OS 

eoMco      ■«■  Tfcoco 


^•^h-i-iiocot^OiooOOOSt^Ot^oOr^OO 
cdcdt^o>id»-«t^t^o>ooi-<idt^oididcot>id 

C<)  C4  rH  fH  ^  rH  M    lO  O  tO  CO  lO  C5  ^  CO  f5  P»  _1_ 


cooococo      csooocooo      ecoi-ioo 
-^eo--id      o>->»«--idco.-<'ooOi-<Pis!J 

tOlOCOCD        COCOCOC^        CO         «10NC4 


eOOOiOCST}i«-iC4cOcOOOr-00^<O^^OOCOOOOOtO^O 

o>cicicoocidide^'r-^tdNeo>-HCOoo6co->i<idrt^h.' 

— i|-H,-l— I        .-ilt^r-lC-^INCOCjNi-li-^CS         •*C0|'«< 


OiOCOi-l 

<3idt^O 


o  CO  CO  lo  >-i  w  c>  T>>     00     cjt-oscoio     oooooscoM  woen^r  ■^ost' 

id'^'coi-i'^t^coci   CO   ostd^^^•-^OQldcoo1-iccgsldo^*o^os 
lo   00   i-ic^toto   00  fin      i-i  »-i   is  ri  o  r~  00  CO  ci  CO  t^  lO -^  CO  i 


rtTft^Kjl       00  lO  ■»«<•«'■*  O       OSeOiON 

oaooodc^      ooto"co'ot-^c50coosi>>" 

—         c*  (M  CO  CC  "  ^ 


eoNioosMt-ooooMooeoot^ooos—i     ioto>-<eo 

g'jit-^pooooot-idtdt-^^odeo'i^osb^odoosoot^od 
CM  N  f5  c»  i-<  CO  N  CO  lo  to  ^  lo  1-1  CO   -Hc^   coK   Tf 

++ 


CMCS         lOCOTl<tO 


^  CO  CO  ^        00 


U3  lO -^        OS  t^  ^  00        ^  W  ■^ -- CO  <-1000  COO  CO 


1— ii-H^H         COCOCOCO         I— li— <r^ 


—I  i-l  CO 


00  N  CO  N  N  ©  00  N  o  lo 'J"  sjs  en  N  a>  OS  CO  CO  o    'lOO 


lOO'*"!*"      eqt^iOrtooooomN-^c^ 


sooos      cocoes 


-HooooomN 


M  M  M  C)       OS       N       rt 


0'4<cocot-'^c^iot>'4t^cxio«ONNoooC4ao^^!P 


"300  l^  00         i-t  »-l  » 


©•- 


,3^ 


t.£-2'£S 


u  «  9 


t-.  *^    rr,    <~i    /-I  ^^  rr^    /-i    tn 


1^ 

a  o 


dd. 

toTS 


Oj  03—3  (CO       • 

f^_fe  2  8  5    - 
S^^dddd..\ 

|BB.r5.f 

IS  &  2    5  I 


'teS 


t  03  O  O  O  O  2j3     ^   " 


1  ki  h  u  q^  U  b  O 

3  3 3 «2  o  a«  2 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Q3g.£f.£f50S| 


S8 


a     £ 


o  o 

03  ^ 


,^  o  oi     oi 

fi  «  !-  (^toK  g  aS 


5|s  il 


.-en  g  M-^    .7; 


e.s.g^.-§  !  g 
c2  £  M    9  •-  - 

•HO        _: 


S  g  oj 
■^   -"3 

-  rt'O 
bjos  > 

§«■§ 
ja-H.2 


g§'-g«S|gS|*3oogSS 


■o  g  ^  a  a  oB.E 

rT.  ,n       o  o  o  c  c 

§.ap.p.& 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


189 


190 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


'Si. 


OS 

^  -a 


Si       g 

?     2 


'tt    o 


•sii 


!=!aag>  t^BBSkag  a  x^  xxxxxsk^  ^>^gH>^>CB 


>» 


»  "> 


!>t:  > 


>"> 


Sa^aS  «aBSaa^  «  g^  abfe3«>^a"  >^aBaaK>bB 


MaMHB  aaBBBHB  M  »  B«Bt:t:HMM  B>ak^Ht:BBM 


HMMHM    g«HM><Ha    M    ^M    gaHGg><B>;    >X>MK«>^HHk! 


» 


>    > 


xxxxx   HMMHK^a  «  aa  Ma«>aHaB  >B»<««Mat><K 


M  MM  M        MMMM 

>  > 


t^t-iO^        M        )-IM)-l 
> 


M  MM  M        MMM^ 

> 


►^M"^        M        MMM 


K«t«it^K  ^<!XHH«MB  M  aa 


>> 


>X>>aBM    BB^Ht-IKMaHH 

M        '-IMK,M        Mti  MM 


WHMHM    ^jMHtxJMWg    «    KM    t^S^<>j>^^^BX 


mm"^  mm 

> 


aXHfrj^   HKWKt«!><H   K   ^x^    wBxa><3a 


>   >   >' 


aK>xaK>^xaM 


HHK«H  KKKXKHM  K  KM  MMMMMMMM  >S>;MaMMMaM 


>  > 


MMMMM    MMMMMMX    M    MM      IMMMMMMM 


•9 

a 
.-se 

o  a  o 
3mo 


O   O) 


".9 


!g-a.-a 


t:t:>aaMMMXM 

►''^mmmm      m 

>> 


S  OS  o 

SCO 


S  Sf  $  a  3  ««  60        a 
S5x!  «  o  .    o  ea         ft 


§-3>>S.;a^ 


n  ea  ^  ;i-  ^ 
►40<lWt 


03  ^ 


*'flar-(03«-_  «„, 

S  «  o 


^^  o  a> 


OO        ^  lO  «C  t^OOO*  y  C^       CO*^  »0  «0  t^  00  OS  O  »-;  N 


W  CO  CO  PO  CC  CO 


^^'^^^^kO*0>0 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


191 


MHH«    KM  H«t:BB       "Bg-g    "-H*^    >'"'    XXXa    H«"    B>    H»t:BB« 


HKk!« 

HII-I 
B> 

«>WMt» 

s^>BB^ 

> 

MM 

B>BM 

BBM 
>> 

^3 

•M^^BB^B 
> 

^KH^^ 

MB 
t-ii-i 

> 

>M'-'MM 

X^>B- 

^X- 

>M 

MMBB 
""^> 

Ml-H 
» 

MM 

BB>BB>B 

MB 

MB>BM 

>B>B'-' 

-\<t 

>> 

MBBB 

MMP-II-I 

BB> 

MM 

^>BM^MB 
> 

KM 

MtlMMM 

BBBM" 
> 

*-'MB 

MB 

«gg£ 

t— It— tl— 1 

>> 

>>tt§B> 

MM 

MMBBB 

t>BB3'-' 
» 

-'MB 

MMMB 
> 

MMS 

MB 

MM 
> 

>>>>>>>< 

1— IhH 

MM 

>       > 

»—(•—)(—• 

»'-' 

"MB 

>B 

MBMB 

MMB 

B> 
> 

K.  HH  t— )  HH  hH  »— 1  K*i 

MKMW 

MM 

MBBBB 

t>  hH  h^  t— t  H- ( 

l-lt-ll-l 
HHWI-l 

l-K-H 

MBMB 
">    > 

MM3 

MB 

1— It— ) 

> 

»>«>>« 

kIKMM 

MM 

K^  hH  l-H  h- (  HH 

K^  t-H  HH  hH  hH 

l-ll-ll-l 

"B" 
> 

> 

MBMB 

MMB 

MM 

K^  1^  1— t  hH  h-l  rH  V-H 
1-^  K^  t-C  HH  ►>  t-t  1-4 

hHI-D-l 

MM 

HBB>B 
>       > 

"gS3" 

"MB 

IHI-C 

>B 

MMMM 

MMB 
i-i 

B^ 
> 

^  hH  M  1— t  H^  HH  )-l 

> 

KMHM 

MM 

MBBBB 

B>>S^ 

BMB 

i-ii-i 

>- 

MMMB 
> 

MM>; 

MB 
"> 

M>i,MMMMkJ 

MM 

MM>BB 

>^>-" 

"BB 

MBMB 

MMB 

BB 
>> 

>BBBB>M 

^»M        M 

W 

. 

MMM> 

MMB 

MB 

MM 

kKXM 

MMBBB 

">^«B 

'"'M'"' 

t-l 

>BtiBB>S 
>    » 

>> 

MMBBB 

>>>BB 

"M" 

l-(l-H 

BB 

MMMt: 

MMB 

Mh-I 

MB 

MM 
> 

>B>BB>^ 
>    » 

^B 


Joss   a"s 

<=  g  «  al'o'-'^ 


2 

o  0^ 


S-C-o  a,      ■}:»       5j;  □ 


R   09   <B 

C  a  «  &  I 


""III 


•3  a?  ^ 


■'='  So.2  2 

0)  D-'C  ®  cfl  3  Q^ 


fll    «*    «*    f  1    rL  (TL  d  Mt 


S  2         °        £m  o         £-2         „  a  03  C3,  a  eo  05  I-    „ 


SS.8S 


00050M         c«mTt<>otD     r~oo»     om     £j  ow«><      mtot*     ooo>     o —' « w s; "« «P 


192 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


'-  > 


^xa 


b^a^a^^>^b>^a 


l-lwl'Sk-ll— ll-ll-ll— H-lhHPSWI— I 
t>        hH  l-H  I— I  ►-!  I— 1 1—1 1— I  HH  I— I  HH  I— I 


|-I>>|— 11-11—11— l>-ll>l—i>-l>>Mi— I 

>^>>>a>'^>>«a^ 


M>aaa^aaaaa3a  a>a^a 

xa^axxxKXkaaa  "aaa> 

xaaaxKxxxxxaa  '-'>aa>; 
">>>   ""  »         > 


x>aa> 


K*^  |_t  ,^  HH  HH  t-^  »^ 


xaxx'-'a>;^a"aa> 


x>;xxaa>5:aa>aa 
x>xxaa>saa>aa 

W-HM    >>'-l^|>l-ll-^> 

aaaa'-'a>5:a'-*aa>; 
aaaasa^>>w'^>« 


xxxxxxxxxxxxx 


>  - 


x> 


xaaaxxxxxxx^s: 


^"  ^>a>:a 


xxaxxxxxxxxaa 
>'^^     WW  www 


«>"xa 


x>xx>a>aaaaaa 

W      1-K.K^wwWW 


>>- 


xxaaxxxxxxxax 

I— *l-|l^l-H      1— IHH    I— IfHhH 


^a> 
> 


xaxxaas:>a>aa> 

WWWWWWI^   Kj.   w»> 


xaxxxxxxxxxxx 

WW      w 


WWW(^, 


xaxxxa>^aaaaa  xaxxaxxxxxxx 


§0.2  So 
o)  C  il?  oo  :3 


SSp 


"O  — —  —  — acloai»a<iua)0>  3 

0^  0^  q;   ^  en  ^ 


•a  rj  0)"— 


2  o-o-o-o  °*-"-: ibis's  fe  g  ^  «^ 
a.^s.^.^.a-'iiaqaaaaaq     -s         H-g  S  c  g  j- giS  a  a  3£  c  a'S  S  S 


H  O  a  a      -Of^' 


C-OQaO  wNm^>n«Dt~.ooo»      Q       OM  ^  «  «  r~  ooo>o -h  Men      ^•Qcor-oo 
Nolc5«coco«Mmec«Mec      9      w ^ ^  m< I"  V*  ■»  iS o us ui      >d>aiaio>n 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  193 


XK« 


t:BBBsaBB«s:gH>t><>>' 


i^XK 


X    ^BBBBBB>X>BB>X,>>>    X 


XXX>XI=!XBBSB 


«3" 

x>>xxa^x>;Xt:axx>;B 

S5>S5>533'~'> 

XXB> 

B»B>S 

BXX 

»xxxxaxx'-'Bxex'^aB 

XXX'-'XXXBXXS 
> 

>>>^ 

g>g^>> 

x^a 

BBBBXXB^BBBX^a>;>B 
>>>      >     >                 >         > 

XXXXBBX5XBS 

> 

>>^> 

>^^$:^> 

XXX 

BB>XX>^>XX>X>X5XS 

r:t:xaxxxBx^x 

l-H  (-t  k"  H-l 

5!>  " 

l-H  H-t  M  HM  HH  >-( 

BBX 
>> 

Ba3gX>g>X>XXXXSBB 

»xaxxxsxx^ 
>  "  > 

g>fe£ 

l-l  l-l  l-H  1^  l-H  1^ 

aax 
>> 

g>s>bgS^«riXxxxaBe 

»XBxxxexx> 

>^>>B> 

XXX 

g5g><>^Bg^^r=hh««55g 

>;:xaxxxaxx> 
>  "  > 

>>>;3 

BB>^-^ 

xax 

^Sg>S><«g^><abd5«5«5 

>^xaxxxsxx> 
>  ^  > 

>>^B 

^B>^-B 

>>x 

>>^^bgS5«55^dg--> 

»XBXXX>XX> 

>B^> 

^>^>B> 

^>x 

^BB>x>saxaBxx->Bs 
>>   >   >     > 

>^XBXXXBXXB 

>B^^ 

B>S^BB 

>   >   HH 

axx 

5gggb>sg><S^5b«"55 

>;^>;;bii:xxbxi*,^ 

>>>B 

'^Bpw'^> 

XXX>XBXBBBB  ttt^ 


>t::^B>>> 


BBBt> 
i-i>-i>-it-i 


B>B>>> 


..  c  c 


O  CS 


S'  c 
33  -3  "O  «  ■?  „ 


c. 


I  a-: 


3x:     £ 


S3^-g  I  ap  *  §  o  §15^  g  g  «CK  =  B  0  p 

a,aiOQOQOOljSOOft.K(EOOK  E-faOO 


t  PA  S 


s   s     -a 


S  !»S«o 


K  a^.-"^ 


a       Si 


l-s 


a 

;p£P;§SS'ag     § 
:  <a  2        2  *    t;   -ij 


194 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


i»         — 


wC^CO-VWtO        t^  00  O;  O  t-H  W  CO  ^ 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


195 


>« 

X 

XX 

aas:aaxaxx> 

1— 11— 1 

l-H  l-H 

>> 

>aBxx'-' 

XX 

t,'^>>'^> 

> 

HH 

> 

a> 

> 

> 

aaxaa>a>>a 

!—(»—(      ►->.    »->    t— '^H 

>> 

a>tr:a>> 

>> 

>'-'aa>> 

> 

xa 

^">>>x 

> 

>> 

aaxx>axax3 

HHI-H 
>> 

>2^aac: 

xa 

><^t>>^ 

>  > 

> 

XX 

^HHXx>xaax> 

HHI-H 

aa^xx^ 

XX 

l-H 

>>        > 

hHt-H 
> 

>sa 

> 

>X 

aaaa>x>x5:> 

X> 

a>aaxa 

XX 

1— (  t— 1  hH  K^  l-H  Kj, 

>a 

>    >> 

« 

>> 

:aaa>xaxx^ 

ax 
> 

labad> 

;>  > 

XX 

l-Ht-H 

aaa>a> 
>>>  > 

HHH-I 

> 

>^d 

X 

l-H 

XX 

axaai^xaxx^ 

ax 

>axxx^ 

XX 

>>>  > 

l-H^ 

^tt^>> 

5>S 
>  > 

X 

I— <  1—1 

>> 

aaaa>xaxx> 

ax 

>aaax^ 

XX 

l-HHH 

K>a^S^ 

t-HHH 

§>t><>> 

>  > 

X 

>> 

aaaa>xaxx> 

ax 

^aaaa> 
>>>> 

XX 

l-H  l-H 

a^a>a 

in  i^s^sa 

>3 
> 

X 

ax 

^Hl-H 

> 

aaxa>xaxxr 

ax 
> 

>axaxa 

XX 

hHhH 

xaa>a5 

HHl-H 

hHI-H 

> 

X 

ax 

aaaa>xaxxs 

ax 

axxaa^ 

XX 

a^a- 

>>^dp> 


x>;X  XX  aa  axaa^xaxx> 


>>>•'>     > 


XX   aaxxx^  xx 


aaxax>  at 
>>  >       > 


ax 


rraa^x>xx> 

"^  1^  l-H  P>  1^  W  f-l 


aa  >aaxx>  xx 


»^»^  aa 


>  ;a>>a 


a  ax  ^a>a>x^xx> 


aa  raaxx^  xx 


:=sg?  >■ 


K*  r*  tr  J>  K^  k"       )-( 


®  a 
0.4- 


«-=  5 

iS  o  c  c 


5  £  o  t-,  i  2.s^tn  ji!<'^  E 03  03-5^=^ ■§«■;;■"  c-^opa 


«2 

..  '- a 


:as 


"O  :S  rt     ''-'•' 


'  a  d  --^  B  u.-_2 
!c  a)  M  oj  c3  .t; 
aScSga 
o  o  ®  o  ts 


;  5      §  2    XI 


Be    "S 


*  *  o 


ifflCQQ        Q        E        cSSoStri^Ec 


o  fc-  t- 


So  a  a 


CNIC^JC^MC^C^        WCSCSC^         N         WW         NWCIWWWC^C^WCS         WW        WWWWWWW        W  WWWWWW        WW 


196 


^  r-X    ~ 


CONCENTRATION  ^OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

)-t[-l  W  >^>-l  l-ll-l         ^  h^l^  ,_,  t_(|_(tHK,l-H 


b<!b<!t>        "^M*^        M  !>  *-•  W-"  b»  "-•        bf"  I-"-"-! '-'        '-'*-'        l-HI-IM        l-H  l-H  M  1-1  hH  l-l 
PSr^K'        l-ll-ll-l        f«i>^l-lt>Sl-tj'l-l        PS  ►>  l-l  l-t  hH        l-ll-H        ►i.b»W        t-l  l-H  b,  ►->.  t-l  S 


>«  > 


K    >>>K>>> 


Kt 


B>BB5:    «K 


H-ll-tl-l        I-I  M  HH  tk  t-l  k^  hi 

>>>  > 


»B 
> 


»B 
> 


>»a>» 
> 


^^XXti   KB 

> 


W^l-I 
> 


>>B>«K^ 

l-l|-|l-<l-H 
> 


>XM    t:B><    «3K>>>>    >BBBB    XX 

IH        ►*         l-(        l-l>>         P-IP-II-I>-I  |-|l-l>>>>        '-' 


>> 


>> 


xxti 

> 


> 


>BK 


BBM 


BBBKB^B 


hH  h-l  I— I  l-l  HH    l-IM 

hHHHI— IhHI— I        I— irN 


» 


>»        > 


BW« 

> 


^^B!»X' 
> 


>BM 


^>X 


I— 1 1— I  I-I  M  I— I  >>  >>        l-<  l-l  hH  I-I  I-I        b("-l        l-'bl'b*'        I-I  I— I  I-I  l-H  ►>  kJ 

w  I-I  >>  "^  I— I '^ '^      I-I  IH  I-I  I— I  t-i      PSi-i      I— iPnPS      hh  m  i-i  k^  >*  rS 

•>>>'^l— !►>  ►>  I-I  I— I  I-I  l-l        l-ll-l        I-I        l-l  1— IHHK* 


>>>>      >    > 


> 


BB    BBBBS> 


>>>!r: 


>•-> 


SXX 


>>ti>>xi 

wk^      I-I      ^ 


>>> 


B>    > 
> 


>>>>>     It; 


>> 


KXX 


>>B>>'Kt 


>>B 


>>B 
> 


BBS:XB>> 


bKbb 


XX 


\=iXX 
>    ^ 


BBB>>><' 
> 


BB    B  ;> 


B^BBB^> 


H- (  h- i  (-H  HH  t— t         hHtV 

HH  HH  KH  l-H  h-H         hH  ►'S 


>xti 


>BB>>X" 


>xx 


JBX 


1— I  I-I  I-I  f^  ►>  ^  M        K^  1^  M  M  I— I        I-I 


>> 


BX« 


>l-l  M  I-I  M  1-1 
^  I-I  I-I  i-»  n  h-i 


'>X 


B>M 
>     ^ 


I-I     ?»i-i;>     )H 


►>^  f-l  1-1  HH  HH        hll— I 

SiB>>>    ^B 


MMB 

H- 1 

> 


»BS>B 


1-1      wi-i>^?-> 


>>M 


B>« 
> 


MP*  »>        >>         h-l 


>>> 


y      3  0 


1     ID 


-  crj  O 


•O-O 


£h 


jB    M«X    >>B>>:BB 


>> 


2-9  & 


«5 


,  G^- 


"^'g  — 


<  OOCS  C*J         c^  » 


O  CO  O         COCCC*3CCCOCOC*5         COfO^HCOCC 


O  ^  C^  CO  -^  »o  '-^ 
t^t.^tN  cocococococor^ 
CO  CO  CO      CO  CO  CO  CO  CO  to  T-Z 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


197 


«>x'-'5: 

>>> 

>>> 

xp^ 

SX    XXX 

XX  >aa 

^»(  t-H  1— 1 1-4 

HH  1— (  1— ( 

BHa 

b>- 

>>  xm^ 

>P  >r 

£      ££•">    £ 

I— I        ^^ 

> 


XXX     >>>  M>>M     ■->  x^s 


>>  "rsa 


I^HHh-tl— lhH^»-4hHt— I 


>                            > 

>x  >t:ix  s:^  >>>          HKHaaaaa^ 

J»               MM        M                                                                  M 

aaxi=i>         xx>     xxa  xs 

M>M                                                                         M         M 

>  f^*  ^  >>  -^  f^*                      >> 

> 

5>  KSjj  ^^  b*^^         ^"'^"^5^3'^ 

M                MMM 

m;>mm^                                                  mMm       m 

XS    XKB    >r    >SX             BBBIi:SB>>;'-' 

'->                >>                ?>                !>M                              MMM         MMMM 

-g><s>          aaa     a>>  5>; 

xa  XXX  SB  >xb<;          ►-bb^bbbb'^ 

M                 MM         I^M                       M                                                           M         MM 
>                                             > 

a^xs>          ss-     a>>  g> 

XB    XXX    BB    >XX              B'^B'~'B3BB'~' 

M               MM        1^^                     M                                                     M        MM 

5PK^>         B>t  «> 

XB    XBB    >>    >BB             BBBBBB>>'^ 

>         MK.?>        M                     j^M                           MMM        MMMM 

S>XKS             GGS       >»    X^ 

MMM 

XX    XXX    >;^    >XX              BB>B>B>;>-^ 

5BXXB 

(i.MM'* 


»— (  I— I  HH  h^  HH         ^^         »■ 

MM         '^'-1 


> 


>xx 


*>X3> 


cocofocc«coeoc*3 


198 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


^ 

HMI-IWMW»l-ll-iMW5>M 
H-IIH                         M 

^MI-IM 

MMMI-H 

MI-IM 

>"g^>^">: 

§ 

_"_K__^'-'«_a"t=i_><_^B 

€^€^ 

BB>^B"    B 

Hi 

"SS  iBS«a"'^S3« 

-->s 

^a>'- 

1— 1 

M 

KH      i»>»-HhHI— 1        M 

M 

BB>B 

l-ll-l> 
h-l 

B"^«a>BB 

i-> 

> 

>>BH 

WMl-ll-l 

MMQ 

1-ll-IK.I-ll-ll-IMM 
►>       "^  l-l  l-l  ►>  l-l  M 

i-( 

K^l— IhHI— IMt— 1^1— lb>-^— "-^'— ll-*!— 11— II— 11— '*— 1 
p-MI-l        ,-1 1_(  ^  HH  f*^  l-l  h-l  M  l-l  l-l  l-l  M  l-l  l-l 
MM                     l-ll-|l-l|-l        I-IMM              >H 

1— IK^hHI-l 

B^^B 

B-^B 

>«»>^>> 

W 

1— (1— 11-11— II— IH-IJ>.»>.^I— II— 1^1— ih>.i-ii— II— II— 1 

aaa  '~'a  *-<  aai-iai-ia'~'3'^ 

>>>B 

>-ll-ll-lhH 

a-> 

>">>>>>> 

o 

1— II— II— II— Ih- II— 1^  1— IK^HHI— II— II— IHHI-HhHI-HI-^ 

a'"""'       aaw"^  '~"~"~'  B'^ 

B>BB 

--^ 

>«^»^>> 

fe 

BBB""  aB>aaaa 

aaaa 

h-ll-ll-l 
> 

>"^>!>^>> 

H 

aa>'^Ba>>;>aa>a>aaaB 

>>>> 

a«> 

P 

>a>'-'a'^>>>aa>a'- 

l-lBl-l                       M  M  M  Hr  W  h-l  M 

B2>a 

B>>B 

mmB 

> 

t:^BB>BS> 

3>aB  B'^>  a'-'>B>»> 


^a"B'^'-'>>B"Bt 


>>;B3Ba"S 


>►— 1 1— I  l-fc  1— ( I— 1 1^ 
>>'^>'-l'^ 


o     ^ 


"3  ° 


t.  <p  a> 
C3  c3  o 


o  ^  te 
do  2 

b  «5  2 


"2  '^ 

OS  a> 

I-   w 

p.  V 

0^-3 


a>  oi 
^& 
o  o 
fta. 


PhW 


°  °  n 
t-    I   ^7  rt  H  il>  X3 

^^-i-i-"2!20'a'"«>s 


a>  03 


?  o  CS  03  I''  03 

)cQCO>2;OE-i 


'J3  03 


I  SI 


ot>-ooa>QrHC^?5'!t¥5^t:rcoc»^»:H^c5 


O^OO^       OOiOaO       030^0       oooooooo 


>  cc  CO  CO       eococoeo       co  co  ^ 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  J^QQ 

>        ►>  >>     >i>  p»  ;>  ;> 


>   >' 


KX^>:t!t'<a>a>'-'  e 


>t>t— "— '        Si  I— I  t-H  HH  M  t-H  t-H  HH  t— (  H-l  (— t  M  h-l        H-l        b>  ^^ 


>>>;>a^t>< 


„W«W,^W«>.«^>.>.>.>.>.^I-I>.|-|        ^^^WW,^>^>^>.J-|^^WWK^MW>.W        >j-J 


HH  l-l  W  W ''^  h-l  hH  >^        HHMhH        t-l  M  I-"  l-( 


-»>SB>>"'^>;>!=!^^BSB>kBX>>;Bt:'-'    >;>t:Bt=iBBKSXBXt:r»'^t!B>;    Bt! 


>»> 


>'-'>' 


^>>>B>B>'' 


^>>BB»'-'>5B>>B-'B> 


B>;B     ^B>;B>t'<^>:^BBB>;B>;>;B>;>;>    BB 


B>SS>>a>a 

r^  1^  hH  H^       HH 


35'*'BB^^BBBB'*'BBBB^'" 


B>>BBKt;5;>>>S>>>BB»S'  BB 


«>5:>;B>B>^ 


;>BKK>'~'>>a>^BBB>t 


K,  K' i_i  *^  >«i ' 


B  >B>B>X>S>>>B>BBB'-'»g  BB 


>^>B>'-'>' 


-t:>BXK>'-'>gS>BBBB>B  >B>B»<>S>>BB>>B>'-'»t;:  BB 


I— (►-^fc-lt— (h-it-Ht— (I— ti— (K>b^M>— '^ 


B>>BBKSS!>>'='«S!>>>«^>S! 
>  > 


i^^i:l»'-'>l 


•^BBB>''^S>B^BBBB>t 
>>   "^  >  > 


B>>B>MS>5:>>Bg>>>B>s!B  BB 


^>?^BB5>'-'>S>>BBBBBB    >BBB>t><>B>BB5!>B>>">>>    B> 


B"^^>5BB 


««^BB>^^BBB    ^ 


p— (^>>i-H        rS  PS  I— (l-<  t^  ►>  l-H  l-l  ^  ►>  l-H  P— I  >>        l-c        ^h^ 


B>>>>;^B^' 


'>>B^B>BSBBBBB'- 


^>^BBWBBB>>BS;>>B"BBB 


>>>      > 


>-'> 


:  c^i2 


tl>    ?^    O  QJ 


©DO 

„  U  o;   O 

-'—  C  O  a; 
a>  -^  'A  ^  S  Q 


S  9   '  "o, 


P  "  c  bti  ?>  i 


fLc&HliicoOraOPHCoaiCJ 


;  3  a  o  == 

)  CO  c   ^-  CJ 


j«;^_  »  m  « 
as  £  «  ®  iB 


-2^1  oga-^ 


^  £  3ac8  « 


■S.D., 

t!  0)  a 


se=-: 


oi  C  (U  u; 


i  o  o  o 


lOtpOp'H        CM  »      Pt( 


247149— 41— No.  1 15 


200 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


.8 


TS 
% 

8 


.^6 


-e        i£, 


©" 
»> 

i 


1— |H-(i— (t-H    I— 1 1— *  *^  >>  *-j,  t^  ►-^  I— t  •->  I— I  f^  l-i.  *->  1— I    I— (1— II— t    >-(»-IH-lhH 


'S>^S'^^^^b«K>'^HS^^Kd  '-'>Ba>'^'-*> 


a«a><xHB>KKMX>K«x«MX^  aBa>KXXH 


>    > 


^XBXX^aXXXBBBBXXBBXK  ^B><>B^BB 


'XBkX'-'BBXKBH>XX«BXX«  >>;B>BB>> 


BXBMX'-'BBXXBBBBXXBBXM  >BB>B^B^ 


BXB«X'-'BBXBBB>BXXB3XX  >BB>B5:^^ 


>>  >>>  >   >> 


"XXXX"BBBBBB>BXXBBXX 


>B>BB>> 


"XBXX"BXXBBB>BXXBBXX  >>^>BB>; 


B^>BX«BBXXXBBBBBXXXX  >"X>BBB> 


^X>XXBBXBBBBBXBXBBXX  BB^BB>>>; 


>X>XX'-'BXBBBB>:XBXBBBX 


«  d  ^'  S^      *5    '    ■  ,^ 


■S.fc'? 


•^^>^>^ 


,  OJ  o  w  ' 


■B»  ;  2-"  00.2 

&   u-.Sf  oStf-^  "  S 

a  o.;i-=i  0?  «  «  > 


5     fc  3-S-2  9-03  o  a  feS  aS  £•§  >2  c  S  a  e-g-S  05  S  «  ^ 


'>>> 


X'-'X> 


:gx 


>r''> 


BB» 


B>>> 


B>>> 


3B>B 


BBS> 


>>t>B 


'BB> 
> 


'BB> 


2-3 


c3  a  , 


2  a  a  £g 
^  o  o  .i:  S 


a>  o  i-H  c^  po -iij*  »n  CD  r^  00  O)  o  ^  c<i  CO  Tji  m  eo  t^  00   Oi  o  »-' cs  c^  tj«  »o  co 
<c  t^  r^  t^  t^  t^  r^  t^  t^  r^  1^  00  00  00  00  00  00  00  00  00   00  os  os  os  os  Oi  os  os 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


201 


>   > 

>>> 

it>l-ll-llv"-<>-IIHI-ll-l 
1        >>«>^»> 

;B^"Bk>i 

M^MK^MHB" 

B>;> 

MBB>>>B>'-' 

:>>B'^>B 

£    ££££>>£    >£«        ^^-    - 

'-ii-'»>i-"-KK 

rS>^            H- 1 1— (i-H  H- 1  ►-;».  HH  ►->.  rS 

:B3"><B>; 

>-l                                        l-l"*^                            1-1               l-l?*M 
>                                                                              > 

►^B>B^t^"^« 

>B> 
> 

^3B>>^^>B 

>>                > 

B>B><B>< 

>>    > 

t-H                ^  •— •  HH  t>  ►::> 

>3b 
> 

B>pB>«B>> 

>KBXtftl 
>     > 

BBBBBB"^"^>B^BBXKK>K 

ttt  |>g=3a 

l-lk>l-l 

>^KK^K>^^ 

BB^BXB 

»-i.  I-H  »^  i-i.  HH  t— ( 

>>     >     > 

>B>>>>^B"><B>'-'B'-'>>BBB 

>>>B>BB>> 
"    >    >       ^ 

> 

BBBBXX 

^S>>;>;>"BBXB"BBBB^BBB 

h;>-i>*^i^>^    i-i*-" 
> 

BX> 

>><XB>B>BK 

^P>^5b 

BB>;>3B'-^>"BBB'-'3'-'B^BBB 

^B«>^>    BB 
> 

>><>   \ 

>BXB>;B>BK 

>>>>^> 

BB>>BB">"3BB"BB^>BBB 

M,^„        M        „        „                     >        K^HHK^ 

>>r:B><BBB> 

BK>B^K><><>k^>><! 

BBBBXK 

3"^BBb'''^^3B*^^B^B>^3B 

t^>^>>^>t 

B«BB^XKX>t^>BX   ; 

BBBBt^B 

>'-!>>>>  ">-'Bs!'^^S'~'B'^>BBB 

>>>I^X5'-'BB    BB>B>B!><B>B>>WBBB5^BB    >B>>>>'~'>"K">'^BB>>B>B 

MMM>M>    MM    K.«    MM^„„    «    M  „  ^  K,  ^  »  „  j,    M       MMM  „  „  M  M  k,  M  ^ 


BBB>^BBB>;  I^XB 
^> 


BBBB>^Bt!X  ;^t:BBXB  '-^>^'-'"'-^BB'-'>B'-'S>BB>B>B 

"»^    ^>^-   >>MMMM      M  MM    M      >M^j^    „    „ 


^Bm   >;::;t 


>BBB3>BB>:    Xt><S'>SXXBBBBBX   ;B^BBX>    B>BBBB'-'B">'-'BBB>5SS>B 


<  ,_|  H^  «  1^  l-l  M  I--  |.^n>-,>^K.'^'^MMMMMl^        ,M>>,MMKN1" 

„„         M  M         „m;>M?-„MMJ^K.;>k^„       ,K^f>MMM 


B"^''^>>BmB 

>        > 


6     iS' 


ffl  ^~  a 


5<=  — 


cs      i!?a^-£i:^— .00) 


■2;'_OmCC  = 


3  g 


s 


era 

■"  o  ox:_  > 
2  =  =  n  ^^TJ 


■§.§ 


0J3. 


a"S.S 


2S  o® 


"^SS 


03  -1^  O;  l_X: 

—    ,  ca  >  a"©  is 
, •o=-cCi.2§~i2g*oo£'-S'§-£aBa2  S^a-cSS 

a;«oo«-oi>.'*cS3ooOS3ocBoS£x3j3t2o®g.-S 


*     '^JH  a  a,  m  "^  ?■«  »  ® 


OOQOOOOCO 


;tC»C»'3»C'C*0iC»CiC»C'Cw^'O»OU7»O*Oi0'O        »C»C"^'CiC»OtC»C»CtC"^»0»OiOW5»0*0»0»d*0 


202 


CONCE^TRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


■2* 


8 


^T3 

9 

n 

o 

e*43 

•j*  a 

.^u 

S 

t> 

a 

o 

1 

e 

HH 

s> 

O. 

?» 

S 

*«         2, 


oS^ 


> 


(-(t-m-m-Hhm— it>>H 


t>.l-l        !-'>>        HHI-H        l-l 


-^    -'    ^'-'  £^  "^  >£    £^ 


^aK>sGkac  x"aa>>aaKS5:aaxaaM'-'K> 


l-c  l-l  I— I  h-l  1— I  K-l  vj  »-l  l-H        1— 1 1— 1 1— I  l-l  l-l  t-l  M  l-l  iv  bd  W  l-l  *-<  I-"-!  !>  lx"-"-l  tx* 

l-l  •>  b.  l-l  b*  ^  l^      !>  l-l  l-l  l-l  HH  l-l  l-l  Pn  ri  PS  l-l      i-ii-ii^?Si-i      PS 

l-l  1^  ^  w  •*■  1-  ->  |-,l_Jj.l>|_|  M        f>         M        ^H 


sKas^xaaa  >«a^>a"saaa>;'-'a>aaaaa 

{>•*■  l-l  -1        1-|K»I-I„        >MI-ll-lt-l        l-l        >.Wf>.        ^ 


^  M  K*^  ►^  h**  t>  *^  t-H  l-l        I— I  >H  I— t  b^  1— I  *— I  >— '  ►-H  I— '  »^  *-H  b»  l^  t>  b>  "^  t^  t-^  ►H  I— I 

PS  ks  b,  PS  Pi  ►>     H     b»     l-l  "-^  l-l  l-l  l-l  h-i  l-l  l-l  l-l  i'     ri  "^  t>  M  i-<  l-l  ►> 
«»*■        ?•  ?•  l-l-l    p,l-l    l-l        l-l    >*l-lf>    >" 


aK^^^ixK^^a  >«a^>>;aaaaa>^>;>t;aaa> 


:xt««i5:Mxaaa  >;'-'aa>;>;'^>aaa>">;>>>;a"a 


-xx>t'<a>aa  ^-'aa>>;"aaaa>;>^aa>xat; 


Ki^^xx„  a  a  a^wM'-'>aaa^  aaa">  ^ 


a'^> 


3><[x!axwKa>;  ^aaaaaa>Mxa>aaa"«"a> 


» 


8  .a 


2    S 


ri     c 


330h 


1'^ 


o    . 

O  9  ; 

r  S  is 


>a 


f>l-IIH 


a>' 


at«<xaKt><aaa  >'^a5>>'-'s>aa>'-'aa>>a*^a         >a' 

Mfj.  l-l        l-l        l-l  ,>l-ll-l        f>l-lM|_,l-l        |_|H<        l-IJ^        Jj.  Ml-I 


>>► 


>>► 


>>► 


'x«>«ww"a  '-^'-'a>;aaa>>^>;>aaaa>;>;a>         >a 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         203 

*>a"«k"«x"aas:'-'  whh mm.-, «;-.««  g«„^gj^„^gj_,j_,^j-j«j-|>^hHi-,wi-,«[>,^i-<«jH 
">  >"  -"-'  ^>'^         >       ^       >     >>  ^"^>>  >^^'-'  "  >^ 


>aa('<Ka>a«  at><>a 
aw     K^wa^g-^hH  > 

t«!k>t'<aaaa(«!aa>aa«aaa'-'t;aa>t><aa 

'-'-'a-'aa'-'Kt'<>;"HH« 
>  '-'>■ 

-"-'«^^aa^'-> 

K                           ►*                                  >        >              IH1-I>H)-II-I 

tHI-I^Mt-l^l-ll-I^M^l-IMM 
^              1-1                     l-l              HI 

-^^^^Kt^a^^^^xt^a^ag^aa^^a-^Ba 

> 

aa^a->>-a 
> 

«a«">xaa""BB^>a"Baa'^""M>k(«! 

"'-'x>;«a'^a>a"""" 

'^a"aa>a"'a 

►Ht-I        P-l 

-««>aa>>aaaaaaa'-'a"'-"-"-"-'wa><« 

a"«  :«aaa>a«-"« 
1  > 

-«-aa^>;"a 

"'^">ak>>^>aakaa^aaa'"'^"«>a« 

--aa-a"a>a">--             -■              .    ^. .    -            ^^^.           ..... 

>                        > 

„„gg„„„„^„„g„„ ■"  -     '    "       ■          .  ^^^^^^^..^.... 

„„WH, 

a-'x 


'3aa>: 


W  >>  H-l  I— I  W  M  h-l        l-l  kH  HH  >-l  h-l  >>►>  I— (>-( 


'-«'-'>aK>>assaKaB' 


a'-'x'-' 

-^a>aaaa-^ 

aaaa  " 

^>'-3axa'^aa>'-'aaaaa"^ 

H  l-l  1-1 

-xaxx 

U-l  1— 1  1— 1  U-J  1— 1  «— f  i— 1  »-      1— <.—.  1—1  .—.■—.  .-J           ,_.._.■_.._,..      ._,._,,_,wj            ^^__^      l-_.l_-.k.      ._.  l_.  _  ._■  t_.  .        l—l  .— 1  1_1  l-_.  1— .  1—1  t-i  k_l  l_J  I   J  »..     I-J  1  J 

> 

^  ^^« 

««««►, 

1-1        ?*■-*               Wl-I        l-l 

> 

»aa>a>aa'-'5:>>i=i  a'^5:'^>>5:t 


>aa>>a>araaa>>> 


aaa^at>'a 


xaax 

hHt— ll-HhH 

> 


>  a!-.> 


-a  '-a'-'a>;aa>>;>aa^a>a>;'^>;a3' 


'xaax 


08-0 
2  OS  o 


s 

"3    ' 

0ST3 


■g  03"o 
"1    i>  15 


IS"? 


I    -I    hr 

I  St,  03  CO 


OT3  o 

CS   Q  u 


M  <fl  5 
,3  a  o-p 


^^"2  0 
fc  g  5  =5 

Ci  K/>  <^  d  ®  • 

a.S^2~  o  X 


J2    '^S--!    '5 
*-•  J  o!  •'^  .    Jjd 


.2.3.3.2 -S£.q?  SS  i  §  ?5  ^-^  §^  8  2  5  3-S  3  3^  ^  i 


-<jm 


03—  O  03  03  C3  05  O 

psmmooooo 


.Q  S  "  c  ca.3^.3.2'o  = 


O  O  C  O  O  «.a  03  3-3'3it  5o=  O  O  C  "5  O  o:  03      „ 

OOOfeiJZCMOO'raaiOoQajOraooOE-ieP^fM    J 


^  a 

aa 

'S'a 

PLiAh 


us  u?  U3  IC  *0  lO  >0  IC  >0  lO  kC  tC  lO  to   CD  V  CD  V  CO  <0  V  CC  ^  CD 


0-— McCTj'.cccr^ocoso  —  Mc?' 


I  cs  c^  c<  c^  C^  c 


■  ul  tC  t^  00  05  O  i— o  « ■«>■     f^ 


204 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


>>  >  >  >> 


> 


>      £>£     > 


■(l-CJ^l— I        ^M 


W  M  l-C  »-lj> 


"'>a^a«K««'^a>S«a"^>>a'^  b^a' 


a>>a>a5:aa"t^"xa'-'aaa>s:«  ><S' 


>a  G" 


>>> 


>> 


>as>s>S!>S"'xas"a"aaaaa  xa' 


'>>x  >> 


aJ^aaa'*'a'*'^'~'X'~'aaa'~"~''*''~'aa  xa^aa*' 


'a>x  >> 


>>^  (_^  K^  H^  K^  HH  l-H  HH  HH  H-(  I— (  1— (  H^  t-H  HH  ^H  hH  f->  t-H  )— 4         K>  ^H  i-H  »—<  ^-^  ►:> 


rN  i-H         l-H  »^  ►^  I— *  "^  ^ 


a>5x  >> 


a>>£i>S;5«g  a>a'-"^  >'^a>"  sa  a^^ 
>  i>  >  >  > 


a>^x  >> 


^H  K.   L^  HH  )— 1  ^  l-H  K.  ►-^  t— 1  k>  )— I  HH  I— I  >-H  t-(  H- 1 1^  hH  H- 1  h-l         HH  ►-(  |-H  t-H  t— 1 1— I  h 
l_l  !■*•  PS  I— 1  ►-»  "*  t-1  1^  f^         KS         fv^         I— I  1^         l-O-l         l-HI— I         I— II— I 

i-l         >_,  i_<  »*  M  1^  l-H  M  1^  1-C  |_|M 


'a>x  >> 


">a>s!=!>s>'-'x'-'>aa'-"-'aa>'-*  aa'-'>s:>aa>K  >> 

^aa^a>aaa^>a^aa"^">aa  xa^-'^a^aaax  ^^ 

>a^^xa>'-'a>a"X'^as:aa'-'ag  aa»>aaxaa  a^ 

ra>>xa>aaaa>xa">>>>>>  aaaaaaaaaa  a> 


o  r^  00  03  o  —  <M  cc -*j«  lo      o  u 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


205 


>>--> 


» 


^>>,^^^^t>>^ 

l-H 

^•^^ 

xxxsa 

>sx>;aa'-"-'sa_x>>xaxx 

>>>""">">>« 

>> 

H-ihH^-* 

"  >>         >              > 

^x^^»>->^>y.x 

x> 

>a« 

xx>xx 

aH>x>H>s^55a--5x>>; 

>>>>w««gaiiia  >«  >>B  >>a>>;  aa>;>;>>K>a'-'>'-"-"-'>>aa 


>>>> 


>^^"'^  -^^  ^^"  ^^3>"  Si 


>i— t^^'^^^l-H^-s.l^l-(l— IHHI— l^^^^l—^l-H 


>> 


>> 


>> 


r» 


i_<  w  Mw  hi  M  hH  ►>  i-H  w  ►>      i-ii>      »>'-"-<      "-I '-1 1>  b<!  >-*      t>L>>!!!! 
i_i  I— ( I— 1 1— I  h- 1      i_|i^|>^i_4K*      K^f^      ^i_(i_i      s>!>Cl'^t>      ILtL'^'"' 

1— II— l>-l>>  >>        •^M  "^l-H         I— ll— I  C  1^  I— 1 1-1  1^        l-IW        »-| 


,        l-l  ''M        I— I 


i-i  i-c  1— 1 1— 1 1— I  h-i  ►>  ►->  1— 1 1— 1 1— I     >it>.     i-ii— ii-i     ►^  K,  >-i  1-1 1-1     >— 1 1— I  !>  l-l  i-<  t-l  >  H  t"*  t"' >•  t>  S  H  t"' H  ^ 


>£::> 


W  MM         i-HI-ll-l        «  WW 


ass     ***'~'aap-<  aa  """a     i-n-iass  aa'~'>  a^aa'"'     wwasa'"' 


>aaa 


>>>> 


i>  I— I  I.H  hH  hH  >-^        »^M        I— l»-l  li^  >^  hH  I— t  H- 1        t— t        PT  I— < 

l-ll-l  hH        hH        WH  (-1  >>•>  l-l> 


il-IWI-IH-ll-ll— O-IWI-IM 


)  l-i  <u« 

•  5?  a< 


on 


!"  in  "  — 

•r!  i:<  fl  <D 


o  «  a 


■  -  „  5       ■  »    1^  S  e 


;|o®^ 


I  &)  lA 


"  S  &    1b 


•9. 

D 

<pq^(i,;i,H5        W        WO 


5ij_o  "  5  ■—  o"  0  oi  -3 


2-9  w 

S2  Z 


.c   « 


MW^iO^Dt-aOOiQi-HN 


*  N      CO-*  lo^h^go^  O^ 


d  Od  Od       0%  ^  O)  ^ 


CO  CO  CO        CO  CO  <0  CO  CO  CO  CO 


coco<o^^^*o^*^«•^^^*^•^*^•^* 


206 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


oS^ 


>>»>xt'<>>">> 


^>     >     >  ^  ^ 


s^»^aB-n->> 


> 


:>>>>Ba'-"-"-'>> 

4         l-HI-l         K,  h-ll-l 


l-l        >-<<-<        »*  Ml-" 


l-l'^2^l-l>ri-ll-l        ►H>-ll-l'f^ 


>BB>        >>>> 
l-lt-ll-l  «-"tH>-lhH 

>> 


„BWH    BBBB 

l-Hl-l  l-( 

> 


^>>a    BB>B 


wi-ii-i       i-ii_ii_t 


>>>B    >;>BB 


l-H  ^  t^  )— •  ►^  »-H  h-i  K^  "--^  t-H  ^       I  h-"  HH  K^  "^ 
'-'>'-<^>^>-l>'^'^'-'-'       .>-HI-(>l-l 


-J  03'; 


.b 


O       •■„  <u  o 


S^^-C 


w     £'3'OS2«i3 


"03X12 

aooooo"      ° 
"-  '"a  o 
n  nx3x:i3x]  a  §  a  ® 


ag 

o  o  o  2 


t:>B    HMB« 

>=*        ►>        M        l-ll-l 


b"^  bH>b 
>>  > 


^^^    BkBB 

r^r^t-t       l-l       l-Hl-l 
>       » 


MKB    «M^^ 


> 


^B^    MMBH 
^  > 


> 


BBB    HtxIBM 

>>>  > 


BBB    MXXK 


HXXM 


^^B    ««B«       B 

!>  >  > 


»>B    >>BB  ^BS:    XKB><1       B 

l-ll-IW  l-l|_ll-|  *^>'^  tt  > 


jWaai^S  gi^-r  > 


coco 


£  «.SS 


■a§^P5ffl(5Smm(5QSMwM3p3o 


CO  CO  C*5        CO  CO  CD  CO 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


207 


>>'-  SB  xa^ 


'>  W>^> 


IX 


>»>';::  >>   «« 


>     > 


a> 


> 


X>>-'>'-'  !i!>>>M  B'-'>>>'-'XMW  KB  >B>>  >BBB 


4^  I— (  K^  w  hH  l-H         HH  ►^i,  ►->  l-H  M         h>  H-l  I— I  H-i )— 1  HH  ►>  J— *  t>         t>  ""^         fc>  »-<  l-H  >— I         h- HH  H-l  I— ( 


'-'>">^B"K 


t-l  l-l  l-H  l-l  >~^  l-l        l-c  1— I  HH  >-l  kJ        •>  b> '—"—"—"-"—"-' Ix*        I— II— I        I— If^b*!— 1        '-lt>t> 


>> 


>BBBt 


1>'-'B 
> 


^^>-> 


)-H  M         '^  HH  1-^  HH  HH         *^  HH         *^         HH  )^  ^         hH         ^H         hH 

>  >        > 


BB^^M 

>BBBBB>;'-'t>< 

KX 

VI 
VIII 

III 
VIII 

>B^" 

>B 

>BB"B>"B 

I  ;^^>" 

BB>^« 

>;>BBBB>;'-*« 

MW 

^XBB 

>^b'~' 

;BB-B>"5 

B«>-r 

> 

>'-'3>;BB'-"-^t^ 

>> 

>B>> 

> 

B>t!BX 

M         "^         HH 

B^K 

B>'-'  :'-'>  IB 

tiBB'-  XXBBX   >>bbb"5:bx   bb   >m>b   b»^ 


>5»>'-'.   BBSIBK    >>>>>>'-"-'t:    k«    BMBB    BB>^B    XBB>S:BBBB"^ 


>>'^> 


>««> 


>r-'B"> 


>>«>«    J>B>BB'-'>B^    >X    BXB^    >>B' 


'BB>' 


=  •0  . 

;3S 


fflliilipiliiiiilfl 


a,--^C'o<i>o6£<jj-2c9'5; 


«o 


S^S3!SS     E:?2^"5"     m- m  «o  t- 00  o>  o  — •  pj      co-*      >osDt~ 

^  <q*  ^  ^  T}<  ^        "^  "^  "^  ^  ^^         »C  10  IC  »C  Ct  »C  O  O  O        (O  <D        CD  CO  CO 


05  o-<e<«co 


«lOCOt^OOOSO^C^W^ 


r^t^t*r»t*t^r^i 


cDt^r^t^t^-      t^r^t^t^t^t^oooooooooo 


t^  t>.  t^  t^      i^  t^  r^  t^  t*      t^  t^  r^  t^  t^  r*  f^  t^  1^  I 


208 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  26. — Flexibility  of  commodity  prices  measured  by  various  criteria  ranked  in  ten 
groups  for  each  criterion  in  order  of  increasing  flexibility — Continued 

DESCRIPTION  OF  CRITERIA  AND  DISTRIBUTION  OF  SERIES 

[Wholesale  commodity  price  indexes  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics,  used  in  each  measure,  are  divided 
into  10  groups,  as  nearly  equal  in  number  as  possible,  with  Items  in  group  I  showing  least  flexibility, 
and  group  X  the  greatest  flexibility] 


Group 

Group  limits 

Num- 
ber of 
items 

Group 

Group  limits 

Num- 
ber of 
items 

Number  of  monthly  changes  in  95  chances,  January 
1926-December  1933 

Number  of  monthly  changes  in  39  chances,  Janu- 
ary 1926-April  1929 

A 
0to4                 - 

619 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

B 
0 

652 

I 

75 
61 
60 
61 
59 
56 
62 
62 
63 
60 

75 

II 

6to7    -. 

1... 

40 

III 

8toll -.- 

2  to  3 

95 

IV 

12  to  16 

4  to  5 

63 

V 

17  to  22               .                       ... 

6  to  8 

58 

VI 

23  to  34 

9  to  13 

60 

VII 

35  to  49 

14  to  20 

63 

VIII 

50  to  77 

21  to  30 

65 

IX 

78  to  92 

31  to  37. 

58 

X 

93  to  95        .                                .  .. 

38  to  39. 

76 

Percent  of  decline  from  June  1929  to  February  1933 

Percent  increase  from  depression  low  to  peak  of  1937 

C 

No  change  and  increases.         -  . 

664 

67 
67 
68 
67 
65 
67 
64 
68 
65 
66 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

D 

Decreases  to  4.3  percent  increase  . 
4.4  to  12.0 

643 

I 

65 

II 

0.1  to  10.9     .                           ... 

62 

III 

11.0  to  17.9 

12.1  to  23.2 

65 

IV 

180  to  25.2 

23.3  to  33.2 

65 

V 

25.3  to  31.3 

33.3  to  45.7 

64 

VI 

31.4  to  37.5                                   .  .- 

45.8  to  57.0 

63 

VII 

37.6  to  43.9             .                     

57.1  to  77.4_ 

66 

VIII 

44.0  to  50.9 

77.5  to  101.0 

62 

IX 

51.0  to  58.9 

101.1  to  172.0 

64 

X 

59.0  to  85.3 

172.1  to  927.2 

67 

Average  of  1929  and  1937  indexes,  less  1932  index,  on 
basis  of  1929=100  percent 

Percent  decrease,  average  of  1929  and  1937  peak.<5  to 
depression  low  index 

E 
-20.6to0.4 

617 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

vn 

VIII 

IX 

X 

F 

Increases  to  8.5  percent  decrease. 
8.6  to  16.7 

640 

I 

61 
60 
62 
61 
63 
62 
60 
62 
63 
63 

63 

II 

0.5  to  7.5 

65 

HI 

7.8  to  12.8 

16.8  to  23.1 

65 

IV 

13.0  to  17.5    .  .    _ 

23.2  to  28.0. 

63 

V 

17.6  to  23.2    

28.1  to  33.6_ 

62 

VI 

23.3  to  27.4 

33.7  to  39.7 

65 

VII 

27.5  to  32.9 

39.8  to  46.3 

65 

VIII 

33.2  to  39.4      . 

46.4  to  57.3... 

65 

IX 

39.5  to  47.5 

57.4  to  65.9 

64 

X 

47.9  to  81.8 

66.0  to  90.0 

63 

Percent  decrease,  average  of  1929  peak  and  1936- 
March  1937  peak,  to  depression  low 

Percent  decrease  from  average  of  1929  and  1937  t 
1932 

G 

Increases  to  7.8  percent  decrease. 
7.9  to  15.3 

655 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

vin 

IX 
X 

H 

28.5  increase  to  0.4  decrease 

0.5  to  7.4 

652 

I 
II 

65 
65 
66 
66 
65 
66 
65 
65 
68 
64 

66 
63 

III 

15.4  to  20.9  .  .  . 

7.5  to  12.7.. .- 

64 

IV 

21.0  to  27.0.... 

12.8  to  18.2.... 

67 

V 

27.1  to  32.7 

18.3  to  23.4 

66 

VI 

32.8  to  38.5 

2.3.5  to  28.5.. 

64 

vn 

38.6  to  45.4 

28.6  to  34.8    

66 

VIII 

45.5  to  55.8 

34.9  to  41.4 

64 

IX 

55.9  to  65.4 

41.5  to  51.6 ...„ , 

51.7  to  81.1 

67 

X 

65.5  to  89.9 

66 

See  footnotes  at  end  of  table 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


209 


Table  26. — Flexibility  of  commodity  prices  measured  by  various  criteria  ranked  in  ten 
groups  for  each  criterion  in  order  of  increasing  flexibility — Continued 

DESCRIPTION  OF  CRITERIA  AND  DISTRIBUTION  OF  SERIES— Continued 


Group 

Oroup  limits 

Num- 
ber of 
items 

Group 

Group  limits 

Num- 
ber of 
items 

Percent  decrease,  average  of  February  1929  and 
February  1937  to  February  1933 

Peak  month  of  index,  1929-31 

I 

644 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

J 
December  1931 

656 

I 

62 
63 
65 
66 
66 
64 
67 
64 
64 
63 

71 

II 

1.7  to  10.0...... 

December  1930  to  November  1931 

June  1930  to  November  1930 

January  1930  to  May  1930 

November  1929  to  December  1929 
September  1929  to  October  1929.. 
June  1929  to  August  1929 

61 

III 

10.1  to  16.3 

59 

IV 

16.4  to  21.0                               .  .  . 

61 

V 

21.1  to  26.2 

60 

VI 

26.3  to  33.3 

72 

VII 

33.4  to  40.1 

72 

VIII 

40.2  to  48.5 

April  1929  to  May  1929 

67 

IX 

48.6  to  57.5 

March  1929 

60 

X 

57.6  to  86.8 

January  1929  to  February  1929... 

83 

Low  month  of  depression  1932-34 

Peak  month  of  index  1936-38 

K 

December  1934 

656 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

L 

December  1938 

650 

I 

80 
56 
50 
88 
52 
71 
40 
82 
78 
59 

158 

II 

December  1933  to  November  1934 
August  1933  to  November  1933... 
June  1933  to  July  1933 

(') 

III 
IV 

July  1938  to  November  1938 

April  1938  to  June  1938 

40 
67 

V 

May  1933 

December  1937  to  March  1938 

September  1937  to  November  1937. 
June  1937  to  August  1937 

61 

VI 

April  1933 

67 

VII 

March  1933 

73 

VIII 

December  1932  to  February  1933- 

July  1932  to  November  1932 

January  1932  to  June  1932. 

April  1937  to  M-ay  1937  .         

62 

IX 
X 

January  1937  to  March  1937 

January  1936  to  December  1936. . 

71 
61 

Average  change  (index  points)  per  change, 
1926-April  1929 

January 

Aggrega 

le  change  (index  points)  less  net 
January  1926-AprU  1929 

change, 

M 
0.0  to  1.6                                   

577 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

0.0 - 

652 

I 

66 
60 
58 
59 
57 
54 
58 
60 
57 
58 

198 

II 

1.7  to  2.2    ..                         .  

(*).. 

ni 

2.3  to  2.6 

(!)    

IV 

2.7  to  3.2 

0.1  to  0.8 

65 

V 

3.3  to  3.8 

9  to  17 

65 

VI 

3.9  to  4.5 

18  to  28 

61 

VII 

4.6  to  5.6 

29  to  45 

65 

VIII 

5.7  to  6.7                                  ... 

46  to  79 

66 

IX 

6.8  to  8.9 

80  to  151 

67 

X 

9.0  to  34.7 

152  up 

65 

'  The  code  numbers  are  those  used  in  the  wholesale  price  bulletins  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics, 
except  that  items  followed  by  "c"  are  composites  as  explained  below. 

» These  measures  are  explained  on  pages  166-168  of  the  text,  and  also  at  the  end  of  this  table.  See  end  of 
table. 

•  These  composites  include  the  following  individual  series  (The  numbers  shown  for  the  individual  series 
In  parentheses  are  their  code  numbers  used  in  the  wholesale  price  bulletins) : 

Composite  2c  includes:  (2)  Corn,  No.  2,  yellow;  (3)  Corn,  No.  3,  yellow. 

Composite  6c  includes:  (6)  Wheat,  No.  2,  red  winter,  Chicago;  (7)  Wheat,  No.  2,  hard;  (8)  Wheat,  No.  1, 
northern  spring;  (9)  Wheat,  No.  2,  dark  northern  spring;  (10)  Wheat,  No.  1,  hard  white;  (11)  Wheat, No. 
2,  red  winter,  St.  Louis. 

Composite  13c  includes:  (13)  Cows,  fair  to  good;  (14)  cows,  good  to  choice. 

Composite  15c  includes:  (16)  Steers,  fair  to  good;  (16)  Steers,  good  to  choice. 

Composite  17c  includes:  (17)  Hoes,  heavy  butchers;  (18)  Hogs,  light  butchers. 

Composite  19c  includes:  (19)  Ewes,  native;  (21)  Wethers,  fed. 

Composite  22c  includes:  (22)  Poultry,  live,  Chicago;  (23)  Poultry,  live.  New  York. 

Composite  24c  includes:  (24)  Cotton,  Galveston;  (25)  Cotton,  New  Orleans;  (26)  Cotton,  New  York. 

Composite  27c  includes:  (27)  E?gs,  Boston;  r28)  Eggs,  Chicago;  (29)  Eggs,  Cincinnati;  (31)  Eggs,  New 
York;  (32)  Ef;gs,  Philadelphia;  (33)  Eggs,  San  Francisco. 

Composite  40c  includes:  C40)  Hay,  clover;  (41)  Hay,  Timothy. 

Composite  55c  includes:  (55)  Pot.itoes,  Boston;  (56)  Potatoes,  Chicago;  (67)  Potatoes,  New  York. 

Composite  59c  includes:  (59)  Wool,  grease,  cloth;  (60)  Wool,  grease,  delaine;  (61)  Wool,  grease,  half  blood; 
(62)  Wool,  grease,  medium;  (63)  Wool,  scoured,  fine; 

Footnotes  continued  on  p.  210. 


210  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  26. — Flexibility  of  commodity  prices  measured  by  various  criteria  ranked  in  ten 
groups  for  each  criterion  in  order  of  increasing  flexibility — Continued 

Composite  65c  includes:  (65)  Wool,  Argentine;  (66)  Wool,  Australian;  (67)  Wool,  Montevideo. 

Composite  68c  includes:  (68)  Butter,  Boston,  extra;  (69)  Butter,  Boston,  1st;  (70)  Butter,  Boston,  2nd; 
(71)  Butter,  Chicago,  extra;  (72)  Butter,  Chicago,  extra,  1st;  (73)  Butter,  Chicago,  1st;  (74)  Butter,  Cincinnati; 
(75)  Butter,  New  Orleans,  fancy;  (76)  Butter.  New  Orleans,  choice;  (77)  butter.  New  York,  extra.  (78) 
Butter.  New  York,  Isf  (79)  Butter,  New  York,  2nd;  (SO)  Butter.  Philadelphia,  extra;  (81)  Butter,  Phila- 
delphia, extra  1st;  (82)  Butter,  Philadelphia,  1st;  (83)  Butter,  St.  Louis;  (84)  Butter,  San  Francisco,  extra; 
(85)  Butter,  San  Francisco. 

Composite  86c  includes:  (86)  Cheese,  Chicago;  (87)  Cheese,  New  York;  (88)  Cheese,  San  Francisco. 

Composite  lOSc'includes:  (103)  Flour,  standard  patent,  Buffalo;  (104)  Flour,  1st,  clear,  Buffalo;  (105)  Flour 
short  patents,  Kansas  City;  (106)  Flour,  straight,'  Kansas  City  (107)  Flour,  standard  patents,  Minneapolis; 
(108)  Flour,  2nd  patents,  Minneapolis;  (109)  Flour,  patents,  Portland,  Ore.;  (110)  Flour,  shorts,  patents, 
St.  Louis  (111)  Fluur,  straights,  St.  Louis;  (112)  Flour,  standard  patents,  Toledo. 

Composite  141c  includes:  (141)  Beef,  fresh,  Chicago;  (142)  Besf,  fresh,  New  York. 

Composite  190c  includes:  (190)  Boys'  shoes;  (192)  Misses'  shoes. 

Composite  194c  includes:  (194)  Shoes,  calf,  blucher;  (195)  Shoes,  calf,  4A;  (196)  Shoes,  cord  tip;  (198) 
shoes,  series  1;  (199)  Shoes,  series  2;  (200)  Shoes,  side  oxford. 

Composite  201c  includes:  (201)  Shoes,  kid:  (204)  Shoes,  brown. 

Composite  202c  includes:  (202)  Shoes,  work;  (203)  Shoes,  elk. 

Composite  205c  includes:  (205)  Shoes,  blucher,  oxford;  (207)  Patent  ieuher  pumps;  (210)  Shoes,  elk, 
colors. 

Composite  206c  includes:  (206)  Shoes,  strap;  (209)  Kid  pumps. 

Composite  212c  includes:  (212)  Steer  hides,  native;  (213)  Steer  hides,  Texas. 

Composite  222c  includes:  (222)  Leather,  oak  bends;  (223)  Leather,  oak  scoured  back;  (224)  Leather,  union 

Composite  261c includes:  (261)  Muslin,  No.  1,  80x92;  (262)  Muslin,  No.  2,  80x80;  (263)  Muslin,  No.  3,  80x80. 
Composite  270c  includes:  (270)  Sheeting,  light;  (271)  Sheeting,  heavy. 

Composite  272c  includes:  (272)  Sheeting,  brown;  (273)  Sheeting,  medium;  (274)  Sheeting,  light. 
Compo.<;ite  281c  includes:  (281)  Yarn,  10/1,  north;  (282)  Yarn,  22/1,  north;  (283)  Yarn,  40's,  south. 
Composite  284c  includes:  (284)  Yarn,  20/2;  (285)  Yarn,  40/2. 

Composite  295c  includes:  (295)  Rayon,  150,  1st;  (296)  Rayon,  150,  2nd;  (297)  Rayon,  300, 1st;  (298)  Rayon, 
300,  2nd. 

Composite  299c  includes:  (299)  Silk,  Canton;  (300)  Silk,  Japan,  white;  (301)  Silk,  Japan,  double  extra; 
(302)  Silk,  Japan,  yellow. 
Composite  303c  includes:  (303)  Silk  yarn,  62/1;  (304)  Silk  yajn,  60/2. 

Composite  306c  includes:  (306)  Silk  yarn,  crepe;  (307)  Silk  yarn,  organzine;  (308)  Silk  yam,  tram. 
Composite  318c  includes:  (318)  Suitings,  serge,  15-ounce;  (319)  Suitings,  serge,  16-ounce;  (320)  Uniform 
serge,  fine;  (321)  Uniform  serge,  medium. 

Composite  325c  includes:  (325)  Yarn,  half  blood;  (326)  Yarn,  fine. 
Composite  341c  includes:  (341)  Jute  yarn,  No.  1;  (342)  Jute  yarn.  No.  2. 

Composite  350c  includes:  (350)  Retort  coke,  Alabama;  (351)  Retort  coke,  New  Jersey;  (352)  Retort  coke , 
Chicago. 

Composite  359c  includes:  (359)  Gasoline,  Northern  Texas;  (360)  Gasoline,  Oklahoma;  (361)  Gasoline, 
Pennsylvania. 
Composite  425c  includes:  (425)  Iron  ore,  Bessemer;  (426)  Iron  ore,  non-Bessemer. 
Composite  427c  includes:  (427)  Pig  iron,  basic;  (428)  Pig  iron,  Bessemer. 

Composite  457c  includes:  (457)  Fence  wire,  annealed;  (458)  Fence  wire,  barbed,  galvanized;  (459)  Fence 
wire  galvanized. 

Composite  462c  includes:  (462)  to  (467)  passenger  cars,  6  series. 

Composite  565c  includes:  (565)  Plate  glass,  3-5  square  feet;  (566)  Plate  glass,  5-10  square  feet. 
Composite  567c  includes:  (567)  Window  glass.  A;  (568)  Window  glass,  B. 

Composite  574c  includes:  (574)  Individual  prepared  shingles;  (575)  Prepared  roofing,  medium;  (576)  pre- 
pared roofing,  slate. 

Composite  666c  includes:  (666)  Fertilizer,  Middle  Atlantic;  (668)  Fertilizer,  New  England;  (670)  Ferti- 
lizer, South  Atlantic,  other;  (671)  Fertilizer,  South  Central  and  Southwest. 
Composite  667c  Includes:  (667)  Fertilizer,  Middle  West;  (669)  Fertilizer,  South  Atlantic,  3-8-3. 
Composite  702c  includes:  (702)  Dinner  sets;  (703)  Dinner  sets,  spray. 
Composite  751c  includes:  (751)  Rubber,  amber;  (752)  Latex  crepe. 
'  Groups  I  and  II  were  combined  for  criterion  L  and  are  indicated  as  group  I. 
*  Groups  1,  II,  and  III  were  combined  for  criterion  N  and  are  indicated  as  group  I. 
«  No  change  in  price  between  January  1926  and  April  1929. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


211 


Table  27. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Percent  of  decline,  1929-33,  compared  with  percent  or  recover,  1933-37.    Commodities  classified  in  10 
groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  D 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

1 

1 

1 
1 
5 
8 
6 
11 

1 

1 
5 
3 

6 
10 



2 

3 

1 
3 
10 

2 
6 
14 

6 
15 

8 

42 
13 
5 

4 

1 

65 

O  IX 

28 
20 
4 
3 

65 

2;   VIII 

5 
1 
9 
9 

4 

10 
4 

10 
13 
8 
3 
4 

67 

O  VII 

2 
3 
4 
3 
9 
12 

13 
9 
7 
8 
3 
2 
2 

67 

S  VI.-. _ ._. 

12 
13 

8 
8 

2 

64 

g  v.. 

12 
13 
13 
3 
3 

63 

1  IV 

13 

12 

9 

5 

65 

3  III. 

11 
16 

5 

1 
1 
1 

68 

II 

14 
16 

3 

63 

I 

31 

65 

Total 

65 

63 

65 

63 

64 

63 

66 

62 

63 

68 

642 

Source:  Criterion  C — Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  D— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE   PRICE  FLEXIBIUTY 


Criterion  C— Percent  decline   from  June  1929  to 
February  1933: 

Oroup Percent  decline 

I... Increase  and  no  change 

II 0.1-10.9 

III 11.0-17.9 

IV.. 18.0-25.2 

V 25.3-31.3 

VI 31.4-37.5 

VII 37.6-43.9 

VIII 44.0-50.9 

IX 51.0-58.9 

X 59.0-85.3 


Criterion  D. — Percent  increase  from  depression  low 
to  peak  of  1937: 

Group —  Percent  increase 

I- Decrease  to  4.3  increase 

II 4.4-12.0 

III - 12.1-23.2 

IV 23  3-33.2 

V 33.3-15.7 

VI 45.8-57.0 

VII 57.1-77.4 

VIII 77.5-101.0 

IX 101.1-172.0 

X 172.1-927.2 


212  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  28.- — Correlation  table  of  comnwdities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 


[Timing  of  predepression  peak  (1929-31)  compared  with  timing  of  depression  low  (1932-34). 
classified  in  10  groups — group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  K 


Oommodities 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

2 
2 
7 
2 
6 
3 
2 
7 
12 

6 

1 
4 
1 
12 
4 
5 
4 

2 
3 
6 
2 
4 
8 
3 

4 
3 
11 
12 
4 
10 

2 
4 
3 
10 
5 

15 
3 
4 

13 

7 
8 
6 

12 
11 

19 

16 
4 
3 
4 

10 
5 
6 
4 
4 
3 

85 

IX 

10 
10 
10 
10 
6 
5 
5 

3 

49 

*Z   VIII 

12 
15 
14 
6 
5 

5 
2 

66 

O  VII 

3 
2 
3 
4 
4 
3 

72 

S  VI 

5 
11 
12 
4 
3 
1 

72 

g  V 

4 
12 
4 
7 
1 

60 

1  IV 

7 
18 
16 

3 

61 

D   III 

4 
8 
10 

59 

II 

6 
13 

61 

I  

37 

71 

Total       ..  . 

80 

56 

60 

88 

62 

71 

40 

82 

78 

59 

656 

Source:  Criterion  K — Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  J — Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  J.— Peak  month  of  index,  1929-31: 

Group—  Month 

I December  1931 

II December  1930-November  1931 

III June  1930-November  1930 

IV January  1930-May  1930 

.  V November  1929-December  1929 

VI _..  September  1929-October  1929 

VII June  1929-August  1929 

VIII April  1929-May  1929 

IX March  1929 

X January  1929-February  1929 


Criterion  K.—liOw  month  of  depression,  1932-34: 

Group—  Month 

I December  1934 

II December  1933-November  1934 

III August  1933-November  1933 

IV.... June  1933-July  1933 

V. May  1933 

VI. April  1933 

VII March  1933 

VIII _ December  1932-February  1933 

IX July  1932-November  1932 

X January  1932-June  1932 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


213 


Table  29. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Timing  of  pre-depression  peak  (1929-31)  compared  with  post-depression  peak  (1936-38).    Commodities 
classified  in  10  groups — group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  L 


Group 

land  n 
combined 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X.. 

6 
6 
14 
7 
7 
15 
12 
21 

4 
1 
6 
1 
9 
3 
3 

6 
1 
3 
5 
9 
3 

10 
2 
8 

7 
5 

4 
3 

5 
18 

9 
2 

7 

17 
7 

21 

8 
5 
6 
7 
13 
9 
1 
4 
5 
4 

84 

XI 

23 
6 
2 
9 
3 
3 

1 
1 

50 

vni .. 

10 
9 
4 
3 
6 
1 
1 
3 

65 

•^  VII... _ 

16 
8 
8 
8 
5 
8 

■ 

72 

^  VI 

8 
7 
12 
7 
1 
2 

72 

S  V 

5 
2 
8 
9 
4 

56 

W  IV .._. 

11 
11 
3 
6 

58 

^  m 

3 
9 

68 

«  n.... . 

28 
41 

59 

^  I 

70 

Total-- 

157 

39 

57 

60 

67 

71 

61 

70 

62 

644 

Source:  Criterion  J— Bureau  of  Labor  statistics.    Criterion  L — Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA   OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  X— Peak  month,  1929-31: 

Group —  Month 

I December  1931 

II December  1930-November  1931 

III June  1930-November  1930 

rV January  1930-May  1930 

V  - November  1929-December  1929 

VI September  1929-October  1929 

VII June  1929-August  1929 

VIU April  1929-May  1929 

IX.- March  1929 

X January  1 929-February  1929 


Criterion  i.— Peak  month  of  index  1936-38: 

Group—  Month 

I  and  II December  1938 

III ...  July  1938-November  1938 

IV April  1938-June  1938 

V December  1937-March  1938 

VI _ September  1937-November  1 937 

VII June  1937-August  1937 

VIII. April  1937-May  1937 

IX... January  1937-March  1937 

X -  January  1936-December  1936 


214 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  30. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  -price  flexibility 

[Timing  of  depression  low  (1932-34)  compared  with  post-depression  peak  (1936-38).    Commodities  classified 
In  10  groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  L 


Group 

I  and  II 
combined 

ni 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X -- 

7 
9 
2 
3 
8 
13 
33 
29 

2 
2 

1 
1 
3 
3 

4 

9 
3 

1 
1 
5 
6 

6 
3 

n 

1 

10 

1 
9 
3 

6  ■ 

7 
11 

7 
16 

n 

7 
9 
10 
3 
3 
3 
7 
4 
6 
9 

5g 

IX 

16 
19 
10 
3 

2 
1 
5 
2 

78 

vni 

16 

18 

81 

W  VII 

9 
16 
6 
1 
2 
1 
2 

5 
5 
6 

2 
3 

39 

is  VI - -- 

r"i5 

9 
12 
4 
3 
4. 

68 

2  V. 

6 
12 
5 
3 
4 

52 

g  IV 

16 
3 

7 
5 

87 

Eh    III 

5 
11 
6 

50 

pj   II 

16 
42 

54 

U   I     

77 

Total 

159 

38 

56 

60 

66 

71 

62 

71 

61 

644 

Source:  Criterion  K — Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  L — Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  K.—liOw  month  of  depression,  1932-34: 

Group —  Month 

I December  1934 

II December  1933-November  1934 

III.. August  1933-November  1933 

IV... June  1933-July  1933 

V May  1933 

VI April  1933 

VII March  1933 

VIII     December  1932-February  1933 

IX... July  1932-November  1932 

X January  1932- June  1932 


Criterion  X.— Peak  month,  1936-38: 

Group—  Month 

I  and  II December  1938 

III July  1938-November  1938 

IV April  1938-June  1938 

v.... December  1937-March  1938 

VI September  1937-November  1937 

VII- June  1937-August  1937 

Vllf... April  1937-May  1937 

IX January  1937-March  1937 

X January  1936-December  1936 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


215 


Table  31. — Correlation  table  of  commod't'ies  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Frequency  of  change  compared  with  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement.    Commodities  classified  in  10 
groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  F 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

vni 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

2 
2 
4 
10 

1 
3 
13  1 

6 
13 

20 

31 

23 

6 

2 

60 

IX .-- 

1 
3 

9I 

18 

63 

<     VIII 

1 

7 
9 
9' 

12 
4 
9 

62 

g     VII. - 

1 
1 
2 
1 

10 
11 

3 

1 
2 

7 
8  ■ 

4 
4 
9 

n ' 

11 
14 
8 
9 

I 
1 

61 

2  VI... 

i — T 
9 

14 
9 
3 

51 

«     V 

8 
7 
10 
5 
3 



m 

E-     IV.. 

7 
13 
6 
3 

67 

tf     III 

8 
14 
8 

59 

"     II 

17 
23 

1 

59 

I 

33 

70 

Total 

59 

61 

58 

55 

56 

62 

61 

62 

64 

62 

600 

Source:  Criterion  A — National  Resources  Committee.    Criterion  F — Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBIUTY 


Criterion  ^.—Number  of  monthly  changes,  in  95 
chances,  January  1926-December  1933: 


Group— 

I 

II..- 


Number  of  changes 

0-4 

5-7 


III .: 8-11 

IV.. 12-16 

V 17-22 

VI. 23-34 

VII 35-49 

VIII 50-77 

IX 78-92 

X 93-95 


Criterion  F. — Percent  of  decrease  from  average  of 
1929  and  1937  peaks  to  depression  low  index: 


Group- 


Percent  decrease 


I Increase  to  8.5  decrefse 

II. 8.6-16.7 

III 16.8-23.1 

IV 23.2-28.0 

V... 28.1-33.6 

VI 33.7-39.7 

VII 39.8-46.3 

VIII 46.4-57.3 

IX 57.4-65.9 

X 66.0-90.0 


247149— 41— No.  1- 


-16 


216 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  32. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Frequency  of  change  compared  with  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement.    Commodities  classified  in  10 
groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  H 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

1 

1 

3 
1 
4 
6 
11 

1 
8 
8 

8 
6 
9 

6 

8" 

13 

28 

27 

7 

1 

1 

60 

IX 

1 

21 
17 
6 
4 
6 

65 

•<     VIII    

3 
6 
4 
5 
« 

8 
7 
8 

14 
16 
12 
4 
2 

62 

5  VII.... 

4 
2 
6 

4 
8 

1 

2 
7 
Ifi 

6 
8 
10 
9 
5 
1 

62 

2   VI 

9 
6 
13 
8 
2 

57 

«    V 

9 
9 
9 
10 

1 

57 

i^     IV 

11 
9 

15 
6 

61 

tf     III 

5 
11 
20 

59 

"     II 

6 
25 

1 

61 

I 

22 

74 

Total.-- 

62 

57 

61 

64 

63 

55 

62 

62 

67 

65 

618 

Source:  Criterion  A— National  Resources  Committee.    Criterion  H— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


DESCEIPTIONS  OF  CRITEBIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PEICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  A. — Number  of  monthly  changes  in  95 
chances,  January  1926-December  1933: 


Group— 

I 

II- 


Number  of  changes 

0-4 

5-7 


III - 8-11 

IV -- --.  12-16 

V - -  17-22 

VI -..  23-34 

VII - - 35-49 

Vm 50-77 

IX - -  78-92 

X - - 93-95 


Criterion  H. — Percent  decrease  from  average  of 
1929  and  1937  to  1932: 

QrQUp Percent  decrease 

I 28.5  increase  to  0.4  decrease 

II 0.&-  7.4 

III 7.5-12.7 

IV- — - 12.8-18.2 

V 18.3-23.4 

VI 23.5-28.5 

VII.- -- 28.6-34.8 

VUI -.- 34.9-41.4 

IX -.  41.5-51.6 

X -- 51.7-81.1 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


217 


Table  33. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

iFrequency  of  change  compared  with  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement.    Commodities   classified  in  10 
groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  I 


Group 

I 

II 

m 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Tota\ 

X 

1 

1 

1 
3 
2 
10 
U 

1 
2 
9 

7 

3 

5 
9 

10 
10 

14 

27 
25 
8 
3 

1 

58 

^  IX 

20 

17 
5 
1 
4 

66 

[j  VIII 

1 
4 
1 
2 

7 

8 

2 
4 
6 
13 

1 
6 
5 
11 

14 
10 
9 
6 

1 

61 

§  VII 

3 

1 
5 
3 
U 
12 

9 
11 
10 
15 
5 
1 

59 

S  VI 

10 
9 

10 
7 
3 
1 

53 

W  V 

7 
8 
8 
5 
2 

61 

&  IV 

4 
12 
11 

8 

61 

g  ni 

II 

12 
12 

59 

12 
26 

1 

1 

58 

I  

24 

73 

Total 

59 

61 

58 

59 

57 

59 

68 

61 

62 

64 

608 

Source:    Criterion  A — National  Resources  Committee.    Criterion  I— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


DESCEIPTI0N3  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALK  PRICE   FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  ^.—Number  of  monthly  changes  in  95 
chances,  January  1926-Deeember  1933: 


Group— 

I 

II. 


Number  of  changes 
0-4 

5-  7 


III --- 8-11 

rv ---.  12-16 

V 17-22 

VI 23-34 

VII 35-49 

VIII 50-77 

IX 78-92 

X 93-95 


Criterion  I. — Percent  decrease,  average,  February 
1929  and  February  1937  to  February  1933: 

Qjoup Percent  decrease 

I Increase  to  1.6  decrease 

II 1.7-10.0 

III.. 10.  1-16.3 

IV 16.4-21.0 

V... _ 21.1-26.2 

VI ....  26.3-33.3 

VII 33.4-40. 1 

VIII _ 40.2-48.5 

IX 48.6-57.5 

X 57.6-86.8 


218 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  34. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distHhuted  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

{Frequency  of  change  compared  with  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement.    Commodities  classified  in  10 
groups — group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  I 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X. 

1 
4 

4 
1 
6 
9 

2 
1 
3 
3 

g 

7 

2 

1 
5 
14 
8 

2 
3 
7 
11 

5 
2 

8 

11 
11 

19 

32 
19 
6 
4 
1 

1 

74 

^  IX 

2 
1 
2 

7 
6 
8 
19 
4 

4 
2 
2 
4 
9 
15 

16 
15 

a 

2 

1 

2 
1 

59 

7,  VIII.... 

11 
9 
7 
8 
2 
5 

64 

§  VII 

10 
10 
6 
10 

4 

62 

S  VI 

7 
9 
10 
7 
5 
3 

59 

W  V 

8 
9 
8 
2 
9 

58 

&  IV 

6 
15 

9 
11 

61 

^  III 

14 
7 
14 

93 

""   n... 

18 

40 

I - 

13 

1 

73 

Total 

62 

63 

66 

66 

66 

64 

67 

64 

63 

63 

643 

Source:  Criterion  I— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  B— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  B.— Number  of  monthly  changes  in  39 
chances,  January  1926-April  1929: 


Oroup— 

I 

II... 


Number  of  changes 

..._ 0 

1 

2-3 

4-5 


III : 

rv 

V 6-8 

VI 9-13 

VII 14-20 

Vni— 21-30 

IX 31-37 

X 38-39 


Criterion  /.—Percent  decrease,  average  of  February 
1929  and  February  1937  to  February  1933: 

QfOQp Percent  decrease 

I_.- Increase  to  1.6  decrease 

II. 1.7-10.0 

III 10.1-16.3 

IV 16.4-21.0 

V 21.1-26.2 

VI _  26.3-33.3 

VII ._ _  33.4-40.  1 

VIIl- 40.2^8.5 

IX 48.6-57.5 

X 57.6-86.8 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


219 


Table  35. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Frequency  of  change  compared  with  timing  of  pre-depression  peak  (192&-31).    Commodities  classified  in 
10  groups — group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION    J 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

vn 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

2 
2 
6 
7 
5 

11 

15 
6 
9 

11 

7 
5 

6 
12 

6 

25 
16 
14 
8 
7 
5 
3 
2 
1 

61 

IX 

1 
3 
8 
10 
11 

10 
16 

5 
2 
2 
4 

1 
2 

1 

63 

<J     VIII - 

1 
2 
7 
11 
12 

9 
10 
7 
3 
5 
2 
5 
3 

60 

"Z     VII 

2 
2 
3 

9 
11 

12 
8 
9 
1 
7 
4 

63 

2   VI 

5 
3 
1 
3 
10 

54 

«   V 

10 
7 
5 
5 
3 

59 

tH        IV 

4 

14 
13 

12 
6 
4 

1 

60 

2   III.-.. 

11 
9 
2 

60 

o  II 

15 
16 

61 

I              

39 

75 

Total.. 

70 

58 

55 

66 

52 

69 

64 

62 

49 

81 

616 

Source:  Criterion  A— National  Resources  Committee.    Criterion  J— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCBIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Crilerion  A. — Number  of  monthly  changes  in  95 
chances,  January  1926-December  1933: 


Group— 
I 

n. 


Number  of  changes 

0-4 

5-7 


in 8-11 

rV 12-16 

V 17-22 

VI. 23-34 

vn ---  35-49 

Vm 50-77 

IX 78-92 

X 93-95 


CriUrion  J.— Peak  month  of  index,  1929-31: 

Group—  ^^^^  month 

I December  1931 

II December  1930-November  1931 

III June  1930-November  1930 

IV T^nuary  1930-May  1930 

v.. .-  .  November  1929-December  1929 

VI September  1929-October  1929 

VII June  1929- August  1929 

VIII April  1929-May  1929 

IX March  1929 

X January  1929-February  1929 


220 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMICS  POWER 


Table  36. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Frequency  of  change  compared  with  timing  of  depression  low  (1932-34).     Commodities  classified  in  lO 
^oups — group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  K 


Group 

I 

n 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

vni 

IX 

X 

Total 

X .-. 

1 

2 
4 
4 
4 
3 
3 
9 

2 
2 

1 
4 
1 
2 
6  ■ 

2 

1 
I 
7 
6 
12 

1 
2 
5 
7 
7 

2 
3 

5 
12 

2 
5 

id' 

21 
23 

15 

15 
11 
7 
3 
4 
8 
7 
3 
4 

61 

IX 

14 
9 
4 
5 
6 
1 
2 
2 

63 

<   vni 

16 

4 

7 

1 
4 
1 

1 

63 

^  vn 

2 
3 

7 

3 
10 
13  ' 

9 
5 
4 

1 
1 

1 

61 

2   VI 

13 
13 
13 
2 
3 

54 

g   V 

4 

7 
8 
6 

59 

^    IV 

—To 

15 
18 
3 

60 

«   III 

9 
7 
13 

59 

"   II 

8 
18 

62 

I 

37 

74 

Total 

76 

55 

47 

75 

47 

66 

38 

78 

72 

62 

616 

Source:  Criterion  A— National  Resources  Committee.    Criterion  K— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCEIPTION9  OF  CEITEEIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  X.— Number  of  monthly  changes  in  96 
chances,  January  1926-December  1933: 


Group— 

I 

11... 


Number  of  changes 

0-4 

5-7 


ni 8-11 

IV 12-16 

V. 17-22 

VI. 23-34 

vn. 35-49 

VIII 50-77 

IX 78-92 

X 93-95 


Criterio-n  K.—Liow  month  of  depression,  1932-34: 


Group 


Month 


I December  1834 

II December  1933-November  1934 

III August  1933-November  1933 

IV June  1933-July  1933 

V_ May  1933 

VI April  1933 

VII March  1933 

VIII December  1932-February  1933 

IX July  1932-November  1932 

X January  1932-JuEe  1932 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


221 


Table  37. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Frequency  of  change  compared  with  timing  of  post-depression  peak  (igse-SSV    Commodities  classified  in 
10  groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  L 


Group 

landn 
combined 

ni 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

vni 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

1 

2 

3 

6 
3 

1 
1 
5 
7 
10 
9 

1 
5 
3 
5 
7 

5 
3 
3 

8 

5 
10 

14 
15 

22 

11 
11 
7 
7 
5 
5 
4 
4 
5 
3 

60 

IX 

3 

1 
4 
5 
9 
15 
26 

13 
24 
3 
2 
3 
1 

63 

^  VIII 

10 
7 
5 
3 
2 
1 

62 

Z  VII 

18 
10 
6 
9 
6 
1 

62 

2  VI 

10 
11 
12 
7 
3 
2 

54 

05  V 

6 
9 
8 
4 
2 

58 

g  IV .;: 

4 
8 
4 
5 

59 

S  m 

5 
17 

58 

o  n 

38 
41 

60 

I 

1 

71 

Total 

141 

37 

54 

50 

64 

73 

58 

68 

62 

607 

Source:  Criterion  A— National  Resources  Committee.    Criterion  L— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CEITEEIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  ^.—Number  of  monthly  changes  in  95 
chances,  January  1926-December  1933: 


Group— 
I 


Number 
of  changes 
0^ 


n 5-7 

III 8-11 

rV 12-16 

V 17-22 

VI 23-34 

VII 35-49 

Vni 50-77 

IX 78-92 

X 93-95 


Criterion  Z.— Peak  month  of  index,  1936-38: 

Group -P*"*  month 

I  and  n. -December  1938 

III July  1938-November  1938 

rV ...April  1938-June  1938 

V December  1937-March  1938 

VI_ September  1937-November  1937 

VII June  1937-August  1937 

Vin April  1937-May  1937 

IX January  1937-March  1937 

X .January  1936-December  1936 


222 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  38. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

lAmplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared  with  timing  of  pre-depression  peak.    Commodities  cla.ssified 
in  10  groups— group  I  lease  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  J 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

vni 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

1 
3 
6 
7 
13 
9l 

2 

6 

4 

11 

7 

9 
12 
6, 

o" 

9 
11 
11 

7 
8 

10 

24 
13 
9 
14 
5 
3 
4 
9 
1 
2 

62 

IX 

12 
12 
8 
1 
2 
2 
4 

1 

65 

'"  VIII. 

5 
5 
8 
9 
11 

11 
5 

11 
7 
7 
2 
2 
4 

64 

§  VII 

1 
2 

1 
5 
7 
17' 

3 

2 
10 
11 
14 

4 
12 
8 
5 
6 
3 
1 

67 

a  VI..-.. 

4 
6 
8 
8 
8 
2 

65 

g  V 

11 

7 
4 

7 

1 

66 

&  IV 

6 

4 
2 

65 

«  III 

5 
7 
8 

65 

II 

14 
4 

63 

I. 

37 

62 

Total    

70 

58 

58 

66 

60 

72 

70 

64 

52 

84 

644 

Source:  Criterion  J— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  I— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  7.— Percent  decrease,  average,  February 
1929  and  February  1937  to  February  1933: 

Qj.Qup Percent  decrease 

I Increase  to  1. 6  deereace 

II 1.7-10.0 

III 10.1-16.3 

IV 16.4-21.0 

V 21-1-26.2 

VI 26.3-33.3 

VII - 33.4-40.1 

VIII 40.2-48.5 

IX 48.6-57.5 

X 57.6-86.8 


Criterion  J^.— Peak  month  of  index,  1929-31: 

Group—  Month 

I December  1931 

II December  1930-November  1931 

III June  1930-November  1930 

IV January  1930-May  1930 

V -.  November  1929-December  1929 

VI September  1929-October  1929 

VII June  1929-August  1929 

VIII April  1929-May  1929 

IX -.  March  1929 

X January  1929-February  1929 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


223 


Tablk  39. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

Amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared  with  timing  of  depression  low  (1932-34).    Commodities  classi- 
fied in  10  groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  K 


Group 

I 

U 

in 

rv 

v 

VI 

VII 

vm 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

4 
2 

1 
2 
4 
6 
7 
8 

2 
2 
4 
3 
5 
9  1 

2 

1 
8 
13 
16 

2 
1 
6 
4 

16 

3 
6 
8 
17 

3 
6 

15 

29 

19 

10 

12 

8 
4 
6 
1 
9 
8 
4 
2 
5 

65 

IX 

18 
16 
10 
8 
2 
4 
4 
6 

62 

"^     VIII 

11 
9 
6 
4 
3 

64 

5    vu 

1 

FT 

2 
3 
2 

67 

2    VI 

11 

11 

5 

0 

1 

63 

g    V 

6 
6 
6 

22 

l~6- 
9 

7 

1 

60 

&    IV 

20 
8 
4 

67 

«   III 

10 
8 
6 

65 

^  II 

14 
8 

1 

1 

63 

I 

39 

62 

Total 

79 

65 

49 

86 

52 

68 

38 

81 

77 

69 

644 

Source:  Criterion  I— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  K— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DKSCBIPTIONS  Of  CBITEBU  Or  WH0LB3ALB  PRICE  FLIXIBIUTT 


Criterion  /.—Percent  decrease,  average  of  February' 
1929  and  February  1937  to  February  1933: 

Qfoup Percent  decrease 

I Increase  to  1.6  decrease 

II 1.7-10.0 

III.   10.1-16.3 

IV 16.4r-21.0 

V 21.1-26.2 

VI 26.3-33.3 

VII 33.4-40.1 

Vni 40.2-48.5 

IX ,... 48.6-57.5 

X 57. 6-86.8 


Criterion  K.—Low  month  of  depression,  1932-34: 
Group—  Month 

I-. December  1934 

II December  1933-November  1934 

HI August  1933-November  1933 

rv. June  1933-JuIy  1933 

V May  1933 

VI AprU  1933 

Vn March  1933 

Vin December  1932-February  1933 

IX July  1932-November  1932 

X January  1932-June  1932 


224 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  40. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Frequency  of  change  compared  with  change  per  change.    Commodities  classified  in  10  groups— group  I 
least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  M 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

2 
4 
17 
4 
7 
6 
5 
4 

4 
9 
6 
11 
7 
3 
5 

7 

10 
8 
8 
7 
6 

6 
10 
6 
8 
4 

5 

7 
3 

8 

6 

8 
6 

15 
3 

8 

7 
6 
3 
3 
2 
6 
7 
10 
7 
5 

60 

^  IX 

1 
7 
9 
3 
2 
7 
3 
7 

r  5- 

2 
1 
3 

13 
6 

12 
7 

63 

^  VIII 

4 
4 
7 
5 
7 
6 
3 
5 

62 

O  VII 

6 
5 
7 
3 
5 
3 
9 

62 

S   VI 

9 
5 
3 
4 
6 

54 

W  V 

4 
6 
4 
3 
2 

57 

&  IV 

8 
2 
2 
2 

57 

g  III 

2 
5 
3 

52 

II 

1 
4 

44 

I 

4 

34 

Total... 

43 

54 

55 

60 

53 

50 

58 

59 

57 

56 

545 

Source:  Criterion  A— National  Resources  Committee.    Criterion  M— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

ijESCEIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  yl.— Number  of  monthly  changes  in  95 

chances,  January  1926-December  1933: 

Qroup Number  of  changet 

I 0-  4 

II 5-  7 

III.. 8-11 

rV 12-16 

V : 17-22 

VI 23-34 

VII 35^9 

VTII 60-77 

IX 78-92 

X 93-95 


Criterion  M. — Average  change  (index  points)  per 

change  January  1926-AprU  1929: 

Qroup Average  change 

I.. 0.0-  1.6 

II 1.7-  2.2 

III 2.3-  2.6 

IV.. 2.7-  3.2 

V 3.3-  3.8 

VI 3.9-  4.6 

Vn 4.6-  5.6 

Vin 5.7-  6.7 

IX 6.8-  8.9 

X 9.0-34.7 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


225 


Table  41.^ — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

Amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared  with  change  per  change.    Commodities  classified  in  10  groups- 
group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 


CRITERION  M 

Group 

I 

n 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

vni 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

2 

3 

5 
10 
5 
6 
7 
8 
8 

2 
10 
8 
6 
8 
7 
5 

4 
15 

7 
12 

6 

2 

7 
9 
8 
4 
4 

6 
6 
6 
8 

7 
7 
9 

16 
3 

10 

6 
5 
7 
6 
4 
4 
8 
7 
5 
4 

63 

IX 

3 
5 
10 
7 
6 
8 
3 
1 
4 

62 

"Z     VIII 

1 
2 
8 
5 
8 
13 
5 

3 
5 
8 
10 
4 
1 
6 
3 

64 

S   VII.-... 

6 
5 
5 
2 
2 
5 
11 

62 

2  VI 

6 
7 
4 
3 
5 
4 

61 

M     V 

5 
3 
5 
8 
4 

58 

^  IV...::::..:: 

5 
4 
2 
3 

55 

3   ni.. 

4 
6 
2 

50 

II 

2 
2 

45 

I    

12 

40 

Total 

66 

56 

58 

59 

67 

64 

58 

69 

67 

66 

569 

Source:  Criterion  M— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  I— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITEEU  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  /.—Percent  decrease,  average  of  February 
1929  and  February  1937  to  February  1933: 
Group —  Percent  decrease 

I Increase  to  1.6  decrease 

II 1.7-10.0 

in 10.1-16.3 

rV 16.4-21.0 

V 21. 1-26.  2 

VI.. 26.3-33.3 

VII 33.4-40.1 

Vni 40.2-18.5 

IX 48.6-57.  5 

X 57.6-86:8 


Criterion  M.— Average  change  (index  points)  per 

change,  January  1926-April  1929: 

Group —  Average  change 

I  .0.0-1.6 

II 1.7-  2.2 

III 2.3-  2.6 

IV 2.7-  3.2 

V 3.3-  3.8 

VI .-  3.9-  4.5 

VII 4.6-  5.6 

Vin 5.7-  6.7 

IX 6.8-  8.9 

X 9.0-34.7 


226 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  42. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Peak  month,  1929-31,  compared  with  average  change  (index  points;  per  change,  January  1926  to  April 
1929.    Commodities  classified  in  10  groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  M 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

vm 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

8 
2 
4 

12 
8 
6 
1 
7 
6 

14 
7 
6 
6 
7 
6 
6 
2 

6 
6 
8 
7 
11 
3 
7 

6 
11 
9 
7 
6 
4 

0 
6 
8 
6 

8 

11 
3 
6 

7 

12 
4 

7 

8 
5 

7 

7 
3 
4 
6 
10 
7 
3 
9 
3 
6 

84 

IX 

4 
6 
5 
4 
9 
6 
8 
4 
4 

50 

^    VIII 

6 
10 
4 
5 
5 
6 
6 
5 

64 

O    VIL 

5 
6 
6 
5 
2 
3 
10 

70 

S    VI 

6 
3 
5 
3 
6 
3 

68 

W     V 

7 
5 

6 
1 
5 

56 

^    IV 

7 
6 
2 
3 

50 

g   ni 

3 

4 
4 

51 

II 

4 

36 

I 

3 

47 

Total 

66 

59 

SB 

59 

57 

63 

69 

60 

67 

68 

676 

Source:  Criterion  J— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  M— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCBIFTIONS  OT  CBITERU  OT  WHOLESALK  PRICE  FLEXIBIUTT 


Criterion  J.— Teak  month,  1929-31: 
Oroup—  Month 

I. December  1931 

II December  1930-November  1931 

ni June  1930-November  1930 

IV January  1930-May  1930 

V November  1929-December  1929 

VL September  1929-October  1929 

VII June  1929-August  1929 

Vni April  1929-May  1929 

IX March  1929 

X January  1929-February  1929 


Criterion  A/.— Average  change  <index  points)  per 
change,  January  1926-Apri]  1929: 

Average 
Group —  change 

I 0:0-  1.6 

II 1.7-  2.2 

UI --...  2.3-  2.6 

rv 2.7-  3.2 

V 3.3-  3.8 

VI 3.9-  4.5 

VII 4.6-  5.6 

VIII 5.7-  6.7 

rX 6.8-  8.9 

X 9.0-34.7 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


227 


Table  43. —  Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Frequency  of  change  compared  with  aggregate  change  less  net  change.    Commodities  classified  in  10 
groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  N 


Group 

I,  II,  and  lU 

combined 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X      -- 

1 
4 
15 

5 
12 

19 

36 

19 

9 

1 

60 

;    IX .... 

1 
8 
16 

27 
10 
7 
2 
2 

63 

§     VIII 

5 
7 
11 

15 
14 
12 
4 
3 

62 

5   vii__. - 

2 
3 

11 
20 

1 
6 
10 

14 
12 
8 
6 
2 
1 
2 

62 

W     VI... 

8 
9 
9 
6 
2 

64 

^     V 

15 
10 
11 
4 
1 

59 

^     IV 

12 
7 

10 
2 

60 

Q 

ni 

34 
44 
70 

60 

n 

61 

I                 

76 

Total 

184 

48 

64 

69 

65 

65 

67 

64 

616 

Source:  Criterion  A— National  Resources  Committee.    Criterion  N— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  /!.— Number  of  monthly  changes  in  95 
chances,  January  1926-December  1933: 


Group— 
I- 


Number 
of  changes 
....    0-4 


II 6-  7 

III 8-11 

IV  -. 12-16 

V  17-22 

Vi  23-34 

Vli 35-49 

VIII..-. 50-77 

IX 78-92 

X : 93-95 


Criterion  iV.— Aggregate  change  (index  points)  less 
net  change,  January  1926-April  1929: 
Group-                                                        Difference 
I,  II,  and  III 0.0 

IV 0.1-    8 

V 9-  17 

VI 18-28 

Vri  -  29-  45 

Vlli 46-  79 

IX 80-151 

X  152  and  up 


228  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  44. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared  with  aggregate  change  loss  net  change.    Commodities  classified 
in  10  groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  N 


Group 

I,  II,  and  III 
combined 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

vm 

IX 

X 

Total 

X    

1 
2 
5 
15 
11 
22 
29 

3 
7 
12 
6 

2 
1 

7 
9 

in 

1 
1 
6 

8 

2 
14 
11 

6 
14 

15 

35 
12 
10 
4 

1 
1 

1 

62 

"     IX - -.. 

20 
13 
4 
3 

7 
2 

64 

O     VIII 

8 
10 
7 
7 
3 
6 
3 
1 

63 

5   VII 

10 
5 
7 
4 
2 
5 
3 

67 

W     VI 

15 
9 
6 
4 
1 
9 

64 

&     V 

7 
11 
8 
6 
6 

66 

g     IV 

10 
11 
7 
8 

66 

Ill 

34 
39 
37 

65 

II    

2 

63 

I 

63 

Total. 

195 

64 

66 

60 

63 

65 

66 

64 

643 

Source;  Criterion  I— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  N— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBaiTY 


Criterion  /.—Percent  decrease,  average  of  Febru- 
ary 1929  and  February  1937  to  February  1933: 

Percent 
Group—  decrease 

I Increase  to  1.6  decrease 

II 1.7-10.0 

III.... 10.1-16.3 

IV 16.4-21.0 

V 21.  1-26.2 

VI 26.3-33.3 

VII.. 33.4^0.1 

VIII. 40.2-48.5 

IX 48.6-57.5 

X.. 57.6-86.8 


Criterion  iV.— Aggregate  change  (index  points)  less 
net  change,  January  1926-Aprll  1929: 

Group—  Difference 

I,  II,  and  III.. 0.0 

IV 0.1-    8 

V 9-  17 

VI 18-  28 

VII 29-  45 

VIII 46-  79 

IX 80-151 

X 152  and  up 


Table   45. — Distribution  of  commodities  according  to  differences  in  rank  under 
various  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Commodities  classified  in  10  groups— maximum  diflerence=9] 


C  orrelation  between 
criteria 

Difference  in  rank 

Same 
rank 

1  and 
less 

2  and 
less 

3  and 
less 

4  and 
less 

5  and 
less 

6  and 
less 

7  and 
less 

Sand 
less 

9  and 
less 

C-D 

29.0 
16.9 
27.0 
21.2 
22.2 
19.6 
24.2 
21.9 
19.7 
21.9 
9.2 
9.0 
11.1 

10.0 

63.0 
42.7 
66.5 
57.0 
59.2 
60.5 
62.9 
64.5 
46.8 
56.8 
25.7 
25.9 
27.8 

28.0 

80.7 
62.5 

85.7 
80.5 
81.6 
73.2 
72.2 
77.1 
66.8 
76.1 
40.8 
45.1 
45.4 

44.0 

89.4 
73.6 
95.2 
92.3 
92.6 
85.3 
84.4 
84.2 
82.2 
86.6 
53.6 
61.4 
60.8 

58.0 

95.2 
85.2 
98.5 
97.0 
97.2 
91.7 
92.0 
90.0 
91.2 
90.5 
67.9 
72.6 
72.8 

70.0 

97.7 
90.8 
99.5 
98.8 
98.7 
96.4 
97.0 
94.1 
96.4 
93.6 
77.1 
84.0 
84.5 

80.0 

99.1 
94.8 
99.8 
99.4 
99.7 
99.0 
98.5 
97.3 
97.4 
96.6 
90.5 
93.5 
92.2 

88.0 

99.6 
96.9 

100.0 
99.6 

100.0 
99.5 
99.7 
98.8 
99.4 
98.3 
97.3 
96.8 
95.7 

94.0 

99.7 
99.2 

100.0 

J-K 

100.0 

A-F. 

A-H 

100.0 

A-I    .          -  . 

B-I 

100.0 
100.0 
99.8 
99.7 
99.2 
99.  1 
98.9 
98.8 

98.0 

A-J.. 

A-K  .... 

100.0 

I-J.... 

100.0 

I-K 

100.0 

A-M 

100.0 

I-M 

100.0 

J-M 

100.0 

Relation  to  be  an- 
ticipated if  purely 
chance   distribu- 
tion  

100.0 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


229 


Table  46. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Frequency  of  change  1926-29  compared  with  frequency  of  change  1926-33.    Commodities  classified  in  10 
groups— group  I,  least  flexible;  group  X,  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  B 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

1^ 
2 

3 

56 
17 

1 
1 

60 

IX.. 

1 

2 

8  ' 

41 
6 
3 
2 

63 

^  VIII 

1 

4 

8 

46 
13 
3 

62 

;  VII_ 

1 
3 

10 
10  ' 

4 

13 

10 

30 

10 

2 

1 

62 

§  VI 

19 
16 
7 
2 

54 

S  V 

2 
3 

8 
17' 

1 
5 
8 

20 
10 
7 
3 

59 

W  IV 

21 
11 
6 
4 

1 

2 

60 

&  III 

24 
26 
14 

60 

«  II 

16 

61 

I 

41 

75 

Total  

71 

39 

88 

55 

57 

55 

63 

66 

57 

75 

616 

Source:  Criterion  A— National  Resources  Committee.    Criterion  B— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBIUTY 


Criterion  A. — Number  of  monthly  changes  in  95 
ohancjs,  January  1926-December  1933: 


Group — 

I 

II. 


Number  of  changes 

0-i 

5-7 


III 8-11 

rv 12-16 

V 17-22 

VI 23-34 

VII_ 35-49 

VIII. 50-77 

IX 78-92 

X 93-95 


Criterion  B.— Number  of  monthly  changes  in  39 
chances,  January  1926-April  1929: 


Group— 
I...- 
II... 


Number  of  changes 

0 

._ 1 


III 2-3 

IV 4-5 

V 6-8 

VI 9-13 

VII 14-20 

Vni 21-30 

IX 31-37 

X 38-39 


230 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  47. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Two  measures  of  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared.    Commodities  classified  in  10  groups- 
group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  F 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

vm 

IX 

X 

Total 

X. - -- 

1 
8 
16 

4 

17 

15 

42 
11 
2 
5 

1 

62 

,,     IX 

1 
2 
5 
15 

2 
6 
16 

23 
11 
4 
8 
2 
1 
1 

62 

r,  VIII 

24 
9 
4 

2 
1 
1 

60 

g    VII^ 

1 

1 

6 

21 

11 

15 

16 
9 
6 
3 
1 

56 

H     VI 

12 
13 
6 
4 
3 
2 

60 

W     V 

1 

6 

26 

15 
10 
3 
4 

1 

60 

fc     IV 

15 
5 
6 
3 

61 

g  III 

1 

24  ' 

19 
5 
5 

61 

II.. 

16 
13 

59 

I .. 

34 

1 

59 

Total 

59 

61 

58 

65 

66 

62 

61 

62 

65 

61 

600 

Source:  Criterion  E — National  Resources  Committee.    Criterion  F — Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA   OF  WHOLESALE   PRICE  FLEXIBIUTY 


Criterion  E. — Average  of  1929  and  1937  indexes,  less 
1932  index,  on  basis  of  1929  equals  100  percent: 


Group — 


Percent 


I -20.6-0.4 

II. .5-7.5 

III 7.8-12.8 

IV 13.0-17.5 

V 17.6-23.2 

VI 23.3-27.4 

VII 27.5-32.9 

VIII.... 33.2-39.4 

IX . 39.5-47.5 

X 47.9-81.8 


Criterion  F. — Percent  decrease,  average  of  1929  and 
1937  peaks  to  depression  low  index: 


Group- 


Percevt  decrease 


I Increase  to  8. 5  decrease 

II 8.6-16.7 

III 16.8-23. 1 

IV 23.2-28.0 

V 28.1-33.6 

VI 33.  7-39.  7 

VII 39.8-^6.3 

VIII. .- 46.4-57.3 

IX 57.4-65.9 

X 66.0-90.0 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


231 


Table  48. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Two  measures  of  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared.    Comunodities  classified  in  10  groups- 
group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  H 


Group 

I 

II 

m 

IV 

V 

VI 

vn 

vin 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

1 

3 

in 

1 

n 

11 

51 
11 
3 

64 

„     IX 

1 

36 
16 
2 

62 

y,   VIII 

33 
13 
2 

1 

62 
61 

§    VII 

2 

7 

8 

8 

36 
14 
2 

3    vi- 

1 

35 
13 
1 

60 
62 
62 

w   v 

39 
12 
1 

fc    IV..... 

6 

43 
12 

«   m 

2 

47 
6 

62 
60 
61 

""   II 

1 

52 

1 

1 

I 

60 

Total 

61 

55 

60 

64 

61 

58 

66 

61 

65 

65 

610 

Source:  Criterion  E— National  Resources  Committee.    Criterion  H— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITEBIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITy 


Criterion  E.— Average  of  1929  and  1937  indexes,  less 
1932  index,  on  basis  of  1929  equals  100  percent: 

Group—  Percent 

1 -20.6-0.4 

n 0.5-7.5 

m 7.8-12.8 

rV 13.0-17.5 

V 17.6-23.2 

VI 23.  3-27.  4 

vn 27.5-32.9 

Vm 33.  2-39.  4 

IX. 39.5-47.5 

X 47.9-81.8 


Criterion  //.—Percent  decrease  from  average  of 
1929  and  1937  to  1932: 

Group—  Percent  decrease 

I 28. 5  increase  to  0.  4  decrease 

11.. 0.5-7.4 

III 7.5-12.7 

IV 12.8-ia2 

V 18.  3-23.  4 

VI 23.  5-28.  5 

vn 28.6-34.8 

VIII 34.9-41.4 

IX.. „ 41.5-51.6 

X 61.7-81.1 


247149— 41— No.  1- 


-17 


232 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  49. — Correlation  table  of  commodities   distributed  according  to  their  ranks 
by  two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

(Amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared  with  change  per  change.    Commodities  classified  in  10  groups- 
group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  M 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X — 

2 

6 
4 
9 
6 
7 
5 
5 
9 

4 
8 
10 
3 
5 
9 
6 

4 
14 

9 
11 

4 

4 

5 
10 
8 
3 
6 

6 
7 
6 
9 

7 
7 

7 

14 
6 

9 

7 
5 
6 
7 
2 
8 
6 
4 
8 
5 

64 

IX 

5 
2 
10 
11 
8 
5 
2 
2 
4 

66 

VIII. . 

2 
1 
9 
3 
12 
11 
4 

6 
5 
7 
5 
5 
5 
3 
4 

64 

hi  VII-. - 

8 
4 
5 
1 
6 
2 
11 

63 

^  VI --.- 

4 
8 
5 
2 
4 
3 

59 

o  v.... - 

6 
2 
6 
5 
6 

61 

S  IV 

7 
1 
3 
2 

54 

g  III 

4 
8 

1 

50 

g  n 

1        6 
1 

45 

gi               

U 

48 

Total 

55 

58 

58 

59 

57 

54 

58 

6D 

58 

57 

574 

Source:  Criterion  H— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  M— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion   H.— Percent   decrease  from  average  of 
1929  and  1937  to  1932: 

Group—  Percent  decrease 

I Increases  too.  4 

n 0.5-  7.4 

in - 7.5-12.7 

IV 12.8-18.2 

V  18.3-23.4 

VI 23. 5-28.  5 

VII 28.6-34.8 

VIII 34.9-41.4 

IX 41.5-51.6 

X --  51.7-81. 1 


Criterion  J\/.— Average  change  (index  points)  per 
change,  January  1926  to  April  1929: 

Group —  Average  change 

I 0.0-  1.6 

II -. 1.7-  2.2 

III 2.3-  2.6 

IV -..  2.7-  3.2 

v.. 3.3-  3.8 

VI. 3.9-  4.5 

VII 4.6-  5.6 

VIII.. 6.7-  6.7 

IX 6.8-  8.9 

X 9.0-34.7 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


233 


Table  50. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  rankt 
by  two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Two  measures  of  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared.    Commodities  classified  in  10  groupe— group  I 
least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  I 


Group 

I 

II 

in 

rv 

V 

VI 

vn 

vm 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

1 

1 

3 

6 
3 

3 

9' 

6 

61 
11 

64 

IX 

2 
2 
10 

33 
24 

62 

vm - 

34 

16 

1 

63 

^  VII 

1 

2 
14 

7 
11 

27 
24 

1 

61 

5  VI 

2 
...... 

10 

4 
2 

g' 

21 

23 

2 

6fi 

a  V 

2 
1 
3 

8  ' 

19 
25 
3 

61 

H  IV 

21 
25 

1 

62 

£!  m 

23 
25 

64 

«  II 

31 
16 

66 

°i.       

47 

63 

Total 

61 

63 

63 

66 

65 

60 

64 

63 

63 

62 

630 

Source:  Criterion  F— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  I— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCKIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBHITT 

Criterion  /.—Percent  decrease,  average  of  February 
1929  and  February  1937  to  February  1933: 


Group — 

I 

II.... 
III.. 
IV... 
V. 


Percent  decrease 
Increase  to  l  .6  decrease 

1.7-10.0 

10.1-16.3 

16.4-21.0 

21.1-26.2 


VI 20.3-33.3 

VII 33.4-40.  1 

VIII 40.  2-48.  5 

IX 48.6-57.5 

X 67.6-86.8 


Criterion  F.— Percent  decrease,  average  of  1929  and 
1937  peaks,  to  depres-sion  low  index: 

Group —  Percent  decrease 

I Increase  to  8.5  deereage 

II 8.6-16.7 

III 16.8-23. 1 

IV 23.2-28.0 

V_ 28.1-33.6 

VI. 33.7-39.7 

VII  _. 39.8-46.3 

VIII 46.4-57.3 

IX 67.4-65.9 

X 66.0-me 


234 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  51. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Two  measures  of  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement  compared.    Commodities  classified  in  10  groups — 
group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  I 


Group 

I 

II 

m 

IV 

V 

VI 

VU 

vm 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

2 

1 
18 

2 

15 

15 

46 
13 

1 
2 

66 

TY    -    -w 

36 
9 
3 

66 

w  vin 

3 

17  1 

33 
12 
1 
2 

64 

Z    vu 

2 

6 

17 

5 
27 

23 
11 
10 

1 

64 

2  VI 

20 
15 
4 
4 
2 

65 

g  V 

19 

2 
26 

17 
8 
6 
2 
2 

64 

H    IV 

26 
11 

3 

66 

«   in 

24 
11 
3 

63 

^  II 

14 

30 
10 

1 

1 

61 

I 

47 

66 

Total 

61 

62 

85 

65 

66 

65 

67 

65 

63 

63 

642 

Source:  Criterion  H— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  I— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


DESCKIPTIONS  OF  CEITEBIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Cyiterion  H.— Percent  decrease  from  average  of 
1929  and  1937  to  1932: 

Qroup —  Percent  decrease 

I... 28.5  increase  to  0.4  decrease 

II 0.5-  7.4 

III 7.5-12.7 

IV 12.8-18.2 

V.., 18.3-23.4 

VI 23.5-28.5 

Vn 28.6-34.8 

VUI 34.9-41.4 

IX 41.5-51.6 

X..., 51.  7-81. 1 


Criterion   I. — Percent   decrease  from   average   of 
February  1929  and  February  1937  to  February  1933: 

Qroup —  Percent  decrease 

I Increase  to  1.6  decrease 

II 1.7-10.0 

III 10.1-16.3 

IV 16.4-21.0 

V 21. 1-26.2 

VI 26.3-33.3 

VII. 33.4-40.1 

VIII 40.2-48.5 

IX 48.6-57.5 

X 57.6-86.8 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


235 


Table  52. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  -price  flexibility 

[Frequency  of  change  compared  with  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement.    Commodities  classified  in  10 
groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  G 


Group 

I 

II 

in 

IV 

V 

VI 

vn 

vni 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

2 
2 

6 
10 

1 

3 

9 

6 
13 

21 

31 

26 

6 

2 

60 

^   ix - 

1 
4 
11 

8 

19 
19 
1 

63 

^   vm 

1 
6 
10 
12 

17 
12 
4 
9 
2 
1 
I 

61 

O   VII 

3 
3 

8 
9 

6 
2 
7 
9 

10 
16 
10 
12 

1 

60 

S  VI 

rrr 

9 
13 
8 
4 
1 

64 

W     V 

3 

1 
8 
12-1 

8 
8 
11 
4 
2 

2 
1 

60 

&     IV.. 

7 
13 
6 
2 

61 

g   m 

10 
17 
10 

60 

II 

■l- 
24 

1 

61 

I 

36 

7S 

Total    

60 

62 

60 

67 

67 

05 

62 

64 

64 

64 

61S 

Source:  Criterion  A— National  Resources  Committee.    Criterion  G— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCEIPTI0N3  OF  CEITE8U  OF  WHOLESALE  PEICE  FLEXIBILITY 

Criterion  Q. — Percent  decrease  from  average  of 
Criterion  ^.—Number  of  monthly  changes  in  95    1929  peak  and  1936-March  1937  peak  to  depression 
chances,  January  1926-December  1933:  low  index: 


Group— 

I 

II... 

ni.. 

IV. 


Number  of  changes 

0-  4 

5-  7 

8-11 

12-16 


V 17-22 

VI - 23-34 

VII 35-49 

VIII 60-77 

IX 78-92 

X 93-95 


Group —  Percent  decrease 

I Increase  to  7.8  decrease 

II 7.9-15.3 

m 15.4-20.9 

IV 21.0-27.0 

V 27.1-32.7 

VI 32.8-38.5 

vn 38.6-45.4 

VIII 45.5-65.8 

IX 55.9-65.4 

X 65.6-89.9 


236 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Tablb  53. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Frequency  of  change  compared  with  amplitude  of  cyclical  movement.    Oommodities  classified  in  10 
groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  H 


Group 

I 

n 

ni 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

vm 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

1 
1 

2 
4 

4 

g 

17J 

4 
6 
2 
6 
7 
4' 

1 
2 
6 
3 
12 
8| 

3 

6 
9 
6 

2 
6 
13 

10 
6 
9 

8 
6 

19 

33 

22 

6 

4 

1 

76 

IX 

2 
2 

1 
6 
6 
7 
21 
3 

16 
17 
4 
3 
3 
1 
3 

68 

«   vm 

9 
16 
10 
6 
4 
6 

66 

g   vn. 

8 
8 
3 
9 
9 
2 
3 

62 

J-   VI. 

9 
10 
10 
6 
4 
3 

62 

fH     V - 

11 
11 
9 
8 
5 

6S 

tl    IV 

6 
11 

7 
13 

61 

tf   in 

12 
9 
14 

03 

°   n 

7 
18 

40 

I 

18 

1 

76 

Total- 

66 

63 

63 

67 

66 

63 

66 

64 

65 

66 

649 

Source:  Criterion  B— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  H— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  B.— Number  of  monthly  changes  in  39 
chances,  January  1926-April  1929: 


Group— 
I. 


n 

in - 

IV - 

V 

VI - 

vn - 

Vin 21-30 

IX 31-37 

X 38-39 


Number  of 
changes 

0 

1 

2-3 

4-5 

6-8 

9-13 

14-20 


Criterion  H. — Percent  decrease  from  average  of 
1929  and  1937  to  1932:  „ 

Percent 

Group —  decrease 

1 28.6  increase  to  0.4  decrease 

n 0.6-  7.4 

m 7.5-12.7 

IV 12.8-18.2 

V 18.3-23.4 

VI 23.  5-28.  5 

VII -...  28.6-34.8 

VUI 34.  9-41.  4 

IX 41.6-51.6 

X 51.7-81.1 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


237 


Table  54. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

(Frequency  of  change  compared  with  timing  of  pre-depression  peak  (1929-31).     Commodities  classified  in 
10  groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  J 


Group 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

1 
4 
9 
13 
5 

12 
10 
6 
6 

13 

8 
10 
6 
9 
8 
11 
4 
3 
1 

5 
9 

11 

22 
15 
7 
11 
10 
5 
3 
7 
3 
2 

64 

IX .— — 

11 

5 
4 
6 
12 
11 

14 
10 
5 
2 
1 
1 
4 

1 

66 

W    VIII - 

1 
3 

5 

7 
14 
111 

13 
8 
8 
7 
6 
4 
2 
4 

64 

5   VII - 

66 

«   VI. 

1 
3 
3 
6 
21 

5 
8 
7 
8 
5 
4 

64 

w     V 

5 
8 
9 
3 
3 

66 

f;^    IV 

8 
4 
4 
2 

66 

«     III - 

64 

^     II.. 

5 

63 

I 

37 

66 

Total    

71 

61 

59 

56 

60 

71 

72 

65 

49 

85 

649 

Soutce:  Criterion  H— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  J— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITKEIA  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  H.— Percent  decrease  from  average  of 
1920  and  1937  to  1932:  p^^^^^^ 

Group —  decreaoe 

1 28.5  increase  to  0.4  decrease 

n... 0.5-  7.4 

III 7.5-12.7 

IV - 12.8-18.2 

V 18.3-23.4 

VI 23»5-28.5 

VTI 2a  6-34. 8 

Vm.... .^ 319-41.4 

IX 41.5-51.6 

X 61.7-81. 1 


Criterion  J.— Peak  mon^h  of  index,  1929-31: 

Group—  Month 

I December  1931 

II December  1930-November  1931 

III.. June  1930-November  1930 

IV Januarj-  1930-May  1930 

V November  1929-Dcccmbcr  1929 

VI September  1929-Octobcr  1929 

VII June  1929-August  1929 

VIII April  192»-Mayl929 

IX.. March  1929 

X January  1929-Februarv  1929 


238         CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  65. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  rank  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

(Frequency  of  change  compared  with  change  per  change.    Commodities  classified  in  10  groups— gioup  I 
least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  M 


Group 

I 

n 

ni 

IV 

V 

VI 

vn 

VUI 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

1 

8 
13 
9 
9 
3 
8 
8 

7 
6 
8 
11 
6 
5 
7 

0 

8 
8 
8 

7 
10 

6 
9 
9 
6 

6 

9 
3 
6 

6 

8 
8 
3 

15 
3 

10 

10 
4 
3 

1 
2 
3 
7 
15 
13 

76 

IX 

6 

10 
7 
7 
3 
8 
7 
8 

3 
2 

1 
4 
7 
10 
17 
3 

58 

«    VIII 

3 

8 
4 
9 
4 
9 
5 

66 

g     VII. 

7 
6 
11 
4 
7 
5 

63 

2   VI 

10 
3 
6 

11 

61 

«     V 

6 
5 
9 
1 

60 

y   IV 

5 
2 
2 

64 

tf   III 

6 
2 

91 

"   n 

1 

40 

I 

* 

Total 

S6 

60 

58 

59 

57 

53 

59 

60 

67 

68 

677 

Source:  Criterion  B— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  M— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCEIPTIONS  OF  CEITERIA  OF  WHOLESALK-PRICE  FLEXIBILITT 


Criterion  B.— Number  of  monthly  changes  in  39 
chances,  January  1926-Aprll  1929: 


Group— 
I 


Number  of  changes 
0 

1 

2-3 

4-5 


II - 

HI 

IV 

V - - 6-8 

VI     9-13 

VIC     - 14-20 

Vm - - 21-30 

IX 31-37 

X 38-39 


Criterion  A/.— Average  change  (index  points)  per 
change,  January  1926-April  1929: 


Group— 

I 

II--.. 
III-.. 
IV... 

v.... 

VI... 
VII  . 
VIII. 
IX... 
X.-.. 


Average 

0. 

1. 

2. 

2. 

3. 

3. 

4. 

5. 


change 
0-  1.6 
7-  2.6 
3-2.2 
7-  3.6 
3-  3.2 
9-  4.8 
6-  5.6 
7-6.7 
8-8.9 
0-34.  7 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


239 


Table  56. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Frequency  of  change  compared  with  affiregate  change  less  net  change.    Commodities  classified  in  10 
groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  N 


Group 

I,  II,  and  UI 

combined 

IV 

V 

VI 

vn 

VIII 

IX 

X 

Total 

X 

5 
16 

27 

43 
15 
6 
1 

75 

^     IX 

2 

2 
6 
12 

2 
11 
12 

4 
14 

19 
12 
6 
3 

58 

flQ 

2 
4 
10 

10 

r;   VIII 

18 
14 
10 
2 

66 

S   VII 

2 
2 

8 
17 

18 
11 
11 
6 
1 

63 

3    VI 

12 
12 
9 
4 

60 

W     V 

15 
11 
16 

68 

fe  IV :::: 

19 

63 

g  III..... 

54 
40 
75 

1 

95 

II 

40 

I 

76 

Total 

198 

65 

64 

62 

66 

66 

67 

66 

652 

Source:  Criterion  B— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  N— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCRIPTIONS  OF  CRITERIA  OF  WHOLESALE-PRICE  FLEXIBILITY 


Criterion  B.— Number  of  monthly  changes  in  39 
chances,  January  1926-April  1929: 


Group— 
I 


II 

III.... 

IV 

V 

VI 

VII 14-20 

Vin 21-30 

IX 31-37 

X 38-39 


Number  of  changes 

0 

1 

2-3 

4-5 

6-8 

9-13 


Criterion  AT. — Aggregate  change  (index  points)  less 
net  change,  January  1926-April  1929: 


Difference 

0.0 

0.1-    8 

9-  17 

18-  28 

2*- 45 

46-79 

80-151 

X 162  and  up 


Group — 

I,  II,  and  m. 

IV 

V. 

VI.... 

VII 

VIII 

IX 


240  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  67. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

[Amplitude  at  cyclical  movement  compared  with  aggregate  change  less  net  change.    Commodities  classified 
in  10  groups— group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  N 


Group 

I,  II,  and  III 
combined 

IV 

V 

VI 

vn 

vni 

IX 

X 

Total 

X - 

1 
3 
6 
U 
13 
19 
30 

2 
2 

4 

9 

9 

2 
2 
6 
6 

12 

1 

9 
9 

6 
10 

11 

6 
12 

16 

31 
15 
6 
6 
1 
2 

63 

a    IX 

24 
9 
9 
1 
7 

68 

Z  VIII - 

14 
10 
1 
3 
9 
6 
1 
3 

63 

o   vn...- 

10 
9 
7 
4 
1 
2 
5 

66 

S   VI 

■■l7- 
6 

7 

4 

7 

63 

«   V 

13 
9 
6 

5 
5 

66 

XI   IV 

9 
14 
9 
8 

68 

O     III 

32 
43 
38 

3 

1 
1 

62 
65 

II       

I 

66 

Total 

196 

66 

65 

60 

65 

65 

69 

63 

649 

Source:  Criterion  H— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  N— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCEIPTION8  OF  CEITEBU  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  FLEXIBaiTY 


Criterion  K.— Percent  decrease  from  average  of  1929 

and  1937  to  1932: 

QpQup Percent  decrease 

1 28.6  increase  to  0.4  decrease 

II. 0.5-  7.4 

m 7.5-12.7 

IV - 12.8-18.2 

v. 18. 3-23.  4 

VI -• 23. 5-28.  5 

VII 28. 6-34. 8 

Vin 34.9-41.4 

IX 41.6-51.6 

X 61.7-81. 1 


Criterion  iV.— Aggregate  change  (index  points)  less 
net  change,  January  1926-April  1929: 

Qroup—  Difference 

I,  II,  and  lU 0.0 

IV 0.1-    8 

V 9-  17 

VL- 18-  28 

VII 29-  45 

VIIL 46-  79 

IX 80-151 

X 152  and  up 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


241 


Table  58. — Correlation  table  of  commodities  distributed  according  to  their  ranks  by 
two  criteria  of  wholesale  price  flexibility 

(Change  per  change  compared  with  aggtegate  change  less  net  change.    Commodities  classified  in  10  gronpa — 
group  I  least  flexible,  group  X  most  flexible] 

CRITERION  N 


Group 

I,  n,  and  ra 

combined 

IV 

V 

VI 

vn 

vni 

IX 

X 

Total 

X - 

20 
13 

0 
12 
11 
16 

9 

4 

i 
4 
6 

5 

3 
11 
6 
4 
3 

4 
6 

7 
6 

6 

6 

1 

3 

3 

2 

18 
16 
17 
12 
3 

66 

w    IX 

2 
8 
7 
13 
15 
15 
6 

69 

"Z  vm 

8 

6 

6 

10 

10 

11 

8 

1 

60 

§    VIL 

7 
9 
6 
6 
10 
11 
3 

68 

S   VI 

3 
3 
7 
4 
11 
10 

64 

W     V 

2 

8 
11 
13 

6 

67 

&    IV 

4 
8 
10 
20 

69 

f^   m 

7 
9 
17 

66 

^   II 

62 

I        

66 

Total 

123 

65 

66 

61 

64 

66 

67 

66 

677 

Source:  Criterion  M— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.    Criterion  N— Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

DESCEIPnONS  OF  CRrTEBIA  OV  WHOLESALB  PEICE  TLEXIBILITT 


Criterion  Af.— Average  cliange  (index  points)  per 

change,  January  1926-ApriI  1929: 

Group—  Average  change 

1 0.0-  l.G 

n 1.7-  2.2 

III 2.3-  2.6 

rV 2.7-  3.2 

V. 3.3-  3.8 

VI 3.9-  4.5 

VII 4.6-  5.6 

VIIL _ 6.7-  6.7 

IX 6.8-  8. '9 

X - 9.0-34.7 


Criterion  iV.— Aggregate  change  (index  points)  less 

net  change,  January  1926-April  1929: 

Group-  Difference 

I,  U,  and  in... 0.0 

IV —  0.1-    8 

V 9-  17 

VI 18-  28 

VII 29-  46 

VIII 46-  79 

IX 80-161 

X - 162  and  up 


APPENDIX  II 1 
CONVENTIONAL  PRICE  LINES 

INTRODUCTION 

The  maintenance  of  price  lines  in  certain  markets  as  an  aspect  of 
nonprice  competition  has  been  described  briefly  in  chapter  III  above. 
Reference  has  also  been  made  to  the  significance  of  the  so-called 
"cash"  discomit  common  in  the  apparel  maricet  as  related  to  price 
lines.  This  appendix  is  presented  in  order  to  describe  these  practices 
more  fully. 

No  attempt  has  been  made,  in  this  appendix,  to  present  appraisals 
of  the  economic  significance  of  these  practices.  It  is  designed  merely 
to  assemble  the  salient  facts  relating  to  each  of  them. 

The  price  behavior  of  many  commodities  is  affected  by  the  practice 
of  "price  lining."  Conventional  pricing  practices  have  become  more 
or  less  firmly  established.  In  both  the  wholesale  and  retail  markets 
the  prices  of  these  articles  show  a  tendency  to  cluster  at  a  limited 
number  of  specific  points  fixed  by  custom;  quotations  at  intermediate 
levels  are  rare  or  absent. " 

The  manifestations  of  this  custom  will  be  discussed  for  wearing 
apparel  and  consumers'  durable  goods,  illustrative  types  of  "price 
lines."  There  is  evidence  that  the  practice  prevails  also  to  some 
extent  in  other  fields,  such  as  certain  kinds  of  drugs,  toiletries,  and 
certain  packaged  groceries. 

WEARING  APPAREL 

The  practice  of  price  lining  is  perhaps  most  fumly  established  in 
the  wholesale  markets  for  wearing  apparel.  As  changes  occur  in 
material  or  labor  costs,  or  in  styles,  the  quality  of  the  garment  is 
changed  in  order  that  it  may  be  sold  at  one  of  these  accepted  levels. 
For  example,  if  the  material  becomes  more  expensive,  the  cost  of  the 
finished  garment  can  be  maintained  at  the  conventional  level  by  the 
use  of  lower  quality  materials  or  less  or  cheaper  trimmings,  or  by 
decreasing  the  amount  of  labor. 

Wholesale  price  lines  are  apparently  somewhat  more  rigidly  main- 
tained for  inexpensive  and  mediuln-priced  merchandise  than  for 
apparel  of  higher  quality.  It  is  reported  that  manufacturers  produc- 
ing dresses  to  wholesale  at  $22.75  and  above  change  their  lines  from 
year  to  year  in  order  to  maintain  the  same  quality. 

Corsets  and  brassieres. — The  corset  and  brassiere  industry  is  an 
excellent  example  of  an  industry  whose  wholesale  price  lines  have 

>  Appendix  II  was  prepared  by  Laura  Mae  Brown.  Acknowledgment  is  due  Miss  VIela  Darnell,  S. 
Kann  Sons  Co.,  Miss  Elizabeth  Farrell,  Julius  Oarflnckel  &  Co.,  and  Mr.  W.  B.  Stringham,  Qeneral 
Electric  Supply  Co.,  for  their  assistance  In  supplying  certain  data  used  in  this  analysis. 

242 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  243 

become  fixed  by  custom.  Under  N.  R.  A.,  conformity  with  these 
price  Hnes  was  made  mandatory.  The  code  for  this  industry,  as 
approved  on  August  14,  1933,  stipulated: 

"Wholesale  prices. — To  maintain  established  trade  practices  and  to  limit  the 
multiplication  of  numbers,  but  without  any  attempt  at  price  fixing,  each  person 
being  free  to  determine  the  value  to  be  given  at  each  price,  the  following  shall  be 
the  wholesale  prices,  per  dozen,  for  sale  to  retailers  (except  chain  stores  selling  up 
to  $1  retail): 


$2.00  doz. 

$8.50  doz. 

$27.00  doz. 

2.25 

10.50 

30.00 

3.25 

12.00 

33.00 

4.00 

15.00 

36.00 

4.25 

16.50 

42.00 

4.50 

18.00 

48.00 

6.00 

21.00 

54.00 

7.00 

22.50 

60.00 

8.00 

24.00 

66.00  and  up."  2 

Testimony  at  the  hearings  indicated  that  the  industry  as  a  whole 
had  for  many  years  observed  these  wholesale  price  lines,  which  cor- 
responded to  similar  price  lines  in  the  retail  market,  and  that  the 
latter  in  turn  reflected  the  accumulated  experience  of  retailers  in 
dealing  with  the  consumer. 

To  an  extent,  therefore,  the  inclusion  of  these  wholesale  prices  in 
the  code  was  simply  a  recognition  of  a  practice  long  established 
through  the  cooperation  of  manufacturers  and  retailers.  Presumably 
some  deviations  from  these  lines  had  appeared  during  the  buyers' 
market  of  1932-33;  the  code  provision  may  have  been  designed  to 
prevent  such  deviations.  The  manufacturers  maintained  that,  as  a 
result  of  the  stabilization  of  prices,  the  retailer  could  carry  a  much 
more  complete  selection  of  sizes  at  each  price  than  would  be  possible 
if  prices  varied  more.  They  contended  that  customers  benefited 
from  such  a  practice.  They  also  argued  that  the  setting  of  wholesale 
price  lines  was  not  equivalent  to  fixed  prices  since  the  manufacturer 
was  completely  unrestricted  as  to  the  quality  of  the  garment  he  might 
sell  at  each  price,  and  since  a  price  line  was  not  restricted  to  a  garment 
meeting  a  standard  specification. 

The  same  general  practice  is  followed  to  a  considerable  extent  in 
the  retail  markets,  although  price  lines  are  less  universal  than  in  the 
wholesale  markets.  The  extent  of  uniformity  is  indicated  by  the 
retail  prices  quoted  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics,  as  of  June  15, 
1938,  by  representative  retailers  in  32  cities.  Of  the  114  quotations 
reported  for  women's  "medium  quality"  woven  elastic  girdles  retaihng 
from  $2.95  to $5.50,  99,  or  87  percent,  were  at  two  prices — $3.50  and  $5. 
One  hundred  ninety-two,  or  85  percent,  of  227  prices  for  foundation 
garments  were  at  the  $3.50  and  $5  lines.  Eighty-one  percent  of  the 
142  prices  reported  for  brassieres  retailing  between  94  cents  and  $1.50 
were  at  the  $1  line;  11  percent  at  $1.50. 

'  National  Recovery  Administration,  Codes  of  Fair  Competition,  vol.  I,  p.  76,  "Corset  and  Brassiere 
Industry,"  sec.  9  (i). 


244  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  actual  distributions  of  these  prices  follow: 

Table   59. — Distribution  of  retail  prices  of  girdles,  foundation    garments,    and 

brassieres 


Girdles 

Foundation  garments 

Brassieres 

Price 

Number 
of  quo- 
tations 

Price 

Number 
of  quo- 
tations 

Price 

Number 
of  quo- 
tations 

$2.95 

4 

2 

1 

32 

1 
2 
1 
1 
1 
67 
2 

$3.19 1 

1 

1 
1 
1 
77 
2 
4 
16 
1 
1 
3 
115 
1 
1 
1 
1 

$0.94     . 

1 

$2.98... 

$3.25 

$1 

115 

$3.39 

$3.29. 

$1.25 

9 

$3.50 

$3.39 

$1.29 

1 

$3.59... 

$3.50        

$1  50 

16 

$3.95 

$3.59 

Total 

$3.98 

$3.95 

142 

$4 

$3.98 

$4.69.. 

$4.69         

$5.... 

$4.95 

$5.50 

$4.98 

$5 

Total 

114 

$5.29 

$5.30 

$5.95 

$5.98 

Total 

227 

Dresses. — Wholesale  price  lines  are  also  maintained  in  the  market 
for  women's  dresses.  Many  firms  manufacture  dresses  to  sell  at  one 
wholesale  price  line  only;  those  producing  inexpensive  garments  tend 
to  maintain  the  same  price  lines  for  many  years.  This  practice  has 
become  so  well  established  that  manufacturers  are  often  described  by 
referring  to  the  price  lines  in  which  they  specialize;  e.  g.,  one  may 
be  known  as  a  "$10.75  house"  or  a  "$14.75  house." 

There  are  two  branches  of  the  dress  industry.  The  first  is  the 
wash  frock  or  "house  dress"  group.  This  branch  of  the  industry 
originated  with  the  manufacture  of  house  dresses  and  aprons — cotton 
garments  which  had  practically  no  "style."  It  now  manufactures 
both  cotton  and  rayon  dresses,  practically  all  of  which  are  styled  for 
street  as  well  as  for  house  wear.  Producers  of  these  garments  usually 
own  their  own  plants  and  ordinarily  are  not  located  in  the  large 
metropolitan  centers. 

The  second  branch  of  the  industry,  usually  known  as  the  women's 
dress  industry  proper,  originated  with  the  manufacture  of  silk  dresses. 
Most  of  the  production  of  this  group  of  manufacturers  is  of  rayon, 
wool,  linen,  and  the  more  expensive  cotton  materials,  since  fewer 
silk  dresses  are  now  sold  than  in  former  years.  Many  of  these  dresses 
are  manufactured  by  contractors;  a  large  percentage  of  the  total 
volume  is  produced  in  New  York  City  in  what  is  known  as  "China- 
town." The  wash  frock  industry  is  more  highly  mechanized  than  is 
the  dress  industry  proper  and  the  frocks  manufactured  by  the  former 
group  tend  toward  the  more  tailored  styles. 

The  more  usual  price  lines  quoted  by  wash  frock  manufacturers  at 
the  present  time  are:  $4.75,  $6.75,  $8.50,  $12.50,  $16.75,  $22.50, 
$30,00,  $31.50,  $33.00,  $42.00,  $45.00  per  dozen. 

All  these  prices  have  been  "standard"  for  many  years,  with  the 
exception  of  the  $31.50  line  which  was  introduced  about  1931.     Close- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


245 


outs,  as  well  as'regular  merchandise,  are  priced  at  these  lines.  Close- 
outs  are  often  made  from  left-over  materials  which  would  ordinarily 
have  been  used  for  more  expensive  lines;  they- are  sold  in  lower  whole- 
sale price  lines  dm'ing  the  latter  part  of  a  season  in  order  to  reduce 
material  inventories  and  to  keep  labor  more  steadily  employed. 
It  is  not  unusual  for  merchandise  which  would  have  sold  at  $45  per 
dozen  at  the  beginning  of  a  season  to  be  sold  at  $22.50  per  dozen  at 
the  end  of  the  season.  This  merchandise  is  used  to  enlarge  the  stocks 
in  the  retail  stores  for  end-of-season  clearance  sales.  Thus  there  are 
in  efi'ect  price  reductions  as  the  season  progresses,  but  they  are  made 
in  conventional  steps  downward. 

Retail  price  lines  are  also  common  in  the  wash  frock  market.  It 
is  imderstood  that  agreements  are  often  made  by  buyers  in  competing 
stores  to  observe  uniform  price  "endings."  Such  agreements  usually 
affect  the  marking  of  lower-priced  merchandise  only. 

The  importance  of  retail  price  lines  in  this  field  is  indicated  by  the 
data  compiled  by  the  Retail  Price  Division  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor 
Statistics.  Of  the  258  prices  reported  during  Jime  1938,  for  dresses 
retailing  between  $1.50  and  $3,  201,  or  78  percent,  were  on  four  price 
lines:  $1.95,  $1.98,  $2.00,  and  $2.98.  The  distribution  of  these  258 
prices  follows: 

Table  60. — Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  wash  frocks 


Number  of 
Price:  quotations 

$1.50 2 

$1.59 1 

$1.69 11 

$1.79 1 

$1.86 1 

$1.88 2 

SI. 94 2 

$1.95 38 

$1.97 1 

$1.98 99 


Number  of 
Price;  quotationi 

$1.99_ 11 

$2.00 39 


$2.25. 
$2.77. 
$2.95. 
S2  98. 
$2.99. 
$3.00. 


3 

1 

12 

25 

2 

7 


Total 258 


The  "accepted"  wholesale  price  lines  in  the  dress  industry  proper 
at  the  present  time  are:  $1.87)^,  $2.25,  $2.87^,  $3.75,  $4.75,  $6.75, 
$7.75,  $8.75,  $10.75,  $12.75,  $14.75,  $16.75,  $19.75,  $22.75,  $29.75, 
$39.75  each  and  over. 

Before  1931  or  1932,  prices  were  25  cents  lower  for  all  garments 
selling  at  $4.75  or  over  (e.  g.,  the  lines  were  $4.50,  $6.50,  etc.).  They 
were  increased  to  their  present  levels  under  an  agreement  instituted 
by  the  Half  Size  Guild,  the  Dress  Creators'  League  of  America,  and 
the  Party  Dress  Guild.^ 

The  development  of  rayon  dress  materials  has  made  possible  the 
introduction  of  cheaper  dresses  during  the  past  10  years.  About 
1930  the  first  $2.25  street  dresses  were  introduced  and  at  the  present 
time  a  $1.87^  line  is  on  the  market.  The  depression  made  this  new 
field  a  very  popular  one;  practically  all  wholesale  lines  below  $4.75 
have  been  introduced  within  the  past  10  years. 

The  retail  market  shows  concentration  at  the  95-cent  price  ending. 
Of  the  215  prices  between  $14.75  and  $19.95  reported  to  the  Bureau 
in  June   1938  on  women's  "medium  quality"  rayon  or  silk  street 

'  N.  R.  A.  Code  Hearings  on  the  Dress  Manufacturing  Industry,  January  7,  1936,  pp.  141  and  186. 


246 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


dresses,  148,  or  69  percent,  were  on  the  $14.95,  $16.95,  and  $17.95 
lines.     These  quotations  were  distributed  in  the  following  manner; 

Table  61. — Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  women's  medium-quality  dresses 

Number  of 
Retail  price:  guotationg 

$16.98 1 

$16.99 1 

$17.50 9 

$17.95 23 

$18.00 1 

$19.75 2 

$19.95 9 


Number  of 

Retail  price:  guotatiom 

$14.75 3 

$14.88 1 

$14.95 56 

$14.98 3 

$15.00 11 

$15.93 1 

$16.50 9 

$16.75 16 

$16.95 69 


Total 215 


Of  242  prices  reported  in  June  1938  on  lower  quality  rayon  street 
dresses  retailing  from  $5.88  to  $12.95,  63  percent  were  quoted  at  four 
prices— $5.95,  $6.95,  $7.95,  and  $10.95.     The  distribution  follows: 


Table  62. — Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  women's  cheap  dresses 


Retail  price: 
$5.88- _. 
$5.94... 
$5.95_.. 
$5.98_.. 
$5.99... 
$6.50- _. 
$6.60... 
$6.90-.. 
$6.95--- 
$6.98-.. 
$6.99- -. 
$7.95... 
$7.98- _. 
$8.00- -. 


Number  of 
Quotations 

1 

1 

24 

14 

3 

5 

1 

14 

35 

7 

10 

57 

11 

1 


Retail  price: 

$8.94.. 
$8.95.- 
$8.98-- 
$9.75.. 
$9.95- . 
$10.00- 
$10.75. 
$10.95- 
$10.98. 
$10.99. 
$11.95- 
$12.95., 


Number  of 
Quotationi 

1 
4 
1 
3 
1 
1 
2 
36 
3 
1 
1 
4 


Total. 


242 

According  to  the  above  distributions,  the  important  retail  price 
lines  for  women's  medium  and  lower  priced  silk  and  rayon  dresses  are: 
$17.95,  $16.95,  $14.95,  $10.95,  $7.95,  $6.95,  and  $5.95. 

One  feature  of  these  last  two  distributions  seems  noteworthy. 
There  is  a  complete  avoidance  of  the  use  of  any  price  between  1  cent 
and  49  cents  over  the  even  dollar.  In  other  words,  of  the  457  quota- 
tions included  in  these  last  two  tables,  every  one  which  is  not  quoted 
at  an  even  dollar  is  at  least  50  cents  over  the  dollar. 

Presumably  this  reflects  the  retailers'  appraisal  of  consumer  psy- 
chology. It  may  well  be  true  that  to  many  consumers  there  is  a 
smaller  psychological  gap  between,  say,  $16.25  and  $16.98  than 
between  $16.98  and  $17.15.  That  retail  pricing  should  reflect  this 
probably  well  warranted  belief  is  natural,  but  the  complete  unanimity 
shown  by  these  distributions  is  very  strOcing. 

Girls'  cotton  dresses. — Girls'  cotton  dresses  are  also  sold  at  "price 
lines."  The  following  distribution  of  523  retail  prices  reported  to 
the  Bureau  as  of  June  15,  1938,  for  girls'  cotton  dresses  retaihng  from 
98  cents  to  $2  shows  that  24  percent  retailed  at  $1.98,  21  percent  at 
$1,  and  12  percent  each  at  $1.19  and  $1.95.  Only  31  percent  of  the 
quotations  were  at  other  prices. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  63. — Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  girls'  cotton  dresses 


Retail  price: 
$0.98- _. 
$1.00-.. 
$1.09--. 
$1.10--. 
$l.ll-_. 
$1.15--. 
$1.19_-. 
$1.25--- 
$1.29--. 
$1.49--- 
$1.59- _- 


Number  of 
guotationi 

31 
109 


2 

2 

26 

65 

19 

2 

2 

1 


Retail  price: 
$1.65.-. 
$1.69-.. 
$1.83-.. 
$1.95... 
$1.97--. 
$1.98... 
$1.99.-. 
$2.00--. 


247 


Number  of 
guotalions 

1 

2 

2 

65 

2 

128 

12 

44 


Total. 


523 


Coats. 


-A  third  example  of  wearing  apparel  sold  at  rigid  price  lines 
IS  women's  and  misses'  coats.  The  most  usual  wholesale  prices  in 
this  field  are:  $6.75,  $10.75,  $16.75,  $22.75,  $26.75,  $39.75  each. 

In  addition  the  following  prices  are  also  quoted  by  many  houses, 
applying  to  both  trimmed  and  untrimmed  coats:  $3.75,  $4.75,  $5.75, 
$8.75,  $12.75,  $14.75,  $19.75,  $29.75,  $49.75  each. 

Women's  hose. — The  importance  retailers  attach  to  hosiery  price 
Hues  is  indicated  in  the  following: 

It  seems  taken  for  granted  that  the  79-cent  retail  price  is  too  firmly  entrenched 
to  be  fooled  with  and  that  any  revisions  on  goods  in  this  price  class  will  be  in  the 
nature  of  construction  changes.'' 

The  prices  reported  to  the  Bureau  in  June  1938  demonstrate  the 
importance  of  the  79-cent  line  and  the  $1  line.  One  hundred  fifty-four, 
or  39  percent,  of  the  396  prices  quoted  were  on  the  $1  hose,  30  percent 
on  the  79  cent,  1 1  percent  on  the  69  cent,  and  7  percent  on  the  89  cent. 
Only  13  percent  of  the  prices  quoted  were  at  other  levels. 


Table  64. 

— Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  women's  hose 

Price 
per  pair 

3-thread, 
45-gau^e 

4-thrcad, 
42-gause 

7-thread, 
42-gaugc 

Total 

Price 
per  pair 

3-thread, 
45-gauge 

4-thread, 
42-gauge 

7-thiead, 

42-gauge 

Total 

$0.69-... 
$0.75.... 

1 

17 
2 

25 

43 
2 
1 
1 
119 
1 
1 

18 
4 

$0.89-..- 
$0v94.... 
$0.95..-. 
$0.97...- 
$1.00.... 
$1.09-... 
$1.15--.. 

Total_ 

6 

1 
2 
1 

95 
1 

15 

9 

12 

27 
1 

$0.77.... 

1 

1 

3 

$0.78...- 

1 

56 

1 

$0.79.... 
$0.80..-. 

13 

50 

1 

1 

10 

1 

27 

32 

154 
1 

$0.84..-. 

1 

3 

19 

$0.85.... 
$0.88.-.. 

3 
2 

5 

1 

141 

119 

136 

396 

Girls'  anklets. — Quotations  for  girls'  mercerized  anklets  reported 
on  June  15,  1938,  to  the  Bureau  show  price  lines  at  lower  levels. 
Forty-seven  percent  of  the  group  retailed  for  29  cents;  26  percent 
retailed  for  25  cents. 


Table  65. — Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  girls'  anklets 


Retail  price: 
$0.25--. 
.27--. 
.28--. 
.29-.. 
.30-.. 
.31--. 


Number  of 
quotations 

....     33 

.;--     1 

3 

..--     60 

1 

1 


Retail  price: 

$0.33-- 

.35.- 

.37-- 

.39-. 


Number  of 
quotations 

.-.-  16 

5 

1 

.--.  7 


Total 128 


*  Knit  Goods  Weekly,  October  17,  1938,  p.  10. 
247149— 41— No.  1 18 


248 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Men's  work  shirts. — In  men's  ready-to-wear,  retail  price  lines  are 
important  in  the  pricing  of  men's  suits,  business  shirts,  underwear, 
socks,  neckties,  and  felt  hats.  The  retail  prices  of  men's  work  cloth- 
ing also  give  evidence  of  price  lining,  although  it  is  not  as  marked  as 
for  women's  clothing.  The  349  retail  prices  reported  to  the  Bureau 
on  men's  work  shirts  retailing  from  39  cents  to  $1  in  June  1938  are 
generally  grouped  at  10-cent  intervals  between  39  cents  and  89  cents: 


Table  66. — Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  men's  work  shirts 


Retail  price: 
$0..39.- 
.45.  _ 
.47.. 
.49.  _ 
.50.. 
.55.- 
.58-. 
.59.. 
.65.. 
.67__ 
.68.. 
.69.. 
.75.. 
.79.. 


Number  of 
quotations 

.-__  13 
2 

1 

-..  22 

4 

....  2 

1 

....  61 

1 

....  3 

1 

.---  55 

....  7 

.---  35 


Retail  price: 
$0.80-- 
.82.. 
.85-- 
.88-- 
.89.- 
.90.- 
.92-. 
.L'l.- 
.95.- 
.98.- 
1.00-. 


Number  of 
quotations 

1 

1 

4 

1 

.---  50 

1 

1 

2 

5 

.--.  39 

....  36 


Total 349 


One  retailer  reported  that  the  chain-store  organization  which  he 
represented  found  that  goods  which  were  changed  in  price  sold  better 
if  they  were  increased  or  reduced  to  an  "accepted"  price  line  rather 
than  to  some  intermediate  price.  For  instance,  shirts  which  had  been 
selling  for  49  cents  would  sell  better  when  placed  in  the  59-cent 
group,  a  price  line  to  which  their  customers  had  become  accustomed, 
than  if  they  were  priced  at  54  cents.  Similarly,  he  said  it  was  nece^ary 
to  observe  customary  lines  even  during  sales. 

It  has  been  pointed  out  that  the  retail  price  lines  found  in  women's 
ready-to-wear  are  the  result  of  two  factors:  (1)  The  rigidity  of  whole- 
sale price  lines,  and  (2)  the  acceptance  of  "customary"  price  lines  by 
consumers  with  the  result  that  retailers  consider  it  expedient  to 
observe  these  conventional  pricing  practices.  For  men's  work  shirts, 
however,  only  the  second  factor  is  significant  since  the  wholesale  quota- 
tions are  flexible,  usually  changing  when  costs  of  production  change. 


VARD    GOODS 

Retail  price  lines  are  also  followed  in  the  merchandising  of  yard 
.goods.  Buyers  who  have  established  price  lines  on  yard  goods  are 
anxious  to  purchase  cloths  which  can  be  retailed  at  established 
prices.  In  order  to  maintain  these  lines  in  the  face  of  changes  in  costs 
quality  is  necessarily  altered,  but  the  variations  are  seldom  great 
enough  to  be  evident  to  the  average  consumer.  In  the  caoe  of  woolens, 
for  example,  the  quality  of  the  cloth  may  be  changed  in  any  of  the 
following  ways:  (1)  Changing  the  construction  of  the  cloth;  (2)  using 
another  grade  of  wool;  or  (3)  introducing  some  reworked  wool  or 
rayon.  In  the  case  of  cotton  goods,  the  price  may  be  stabilized  by 
varying  the  quality  of  the  yarn  used,  and,  if  the  cloth  is  printed,  by 
varying  the  number  of  colors  and  the  elaborateness  of  the  design. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  249 

Retail  prices  on  printed  percales,  80  x  80  construction,  reported  to 
the  Bureau  as  of  December  1938  indicate  the  prevalence  of  price 
lining.  Two  price  lines — 19  cents  and  25  cents — accounted  for  114  of 
the  134  quotations. 

Table  67. — Distribution  of  retail  prices  for  printed  percales 


Number  of 
Retail  price:  quotations 

$0.14 1 

$0.15 3 

$0.17 6 

$0.19 46 

$0,2r. 1 

$0.22 6 


Number  of 
Retail  price:  quotations 

$0.23 2 

$0.24 1 

$0.25 68 


Total 134 


CONSUMERS  DURABLE  GOODS 

The  retail  list  prices  of  certain  kinds  of  consumers'  durable  goods 
also  show  evidence  of  established  price  lines,  although  the  practice  is 
not  as  universal  in  this  field  as  in  the  apparel  markets.  Many  elec- 
trical appliances,  for  example,  are  regularly  priced  at  5  cents  under  the 
even  $10  mark.  As  in  the  case  of  apparel,  price  lines  are  more  com- 
mon in  connection  with  the  sale  of  merchandise  designed  for  consum- 
ers in  the  low  and  middle  income  brackets  than  for  goods  destined  for 
the  less  price-conscious  luxury  trade. 

Washing  machines  and  vacuum  cleaners. — In  the  sale  of  both  washing 
machines  and  vacuum  cleaners  it  seems  to  be  the  accepted  practice 
for  retail  prices  to  be  quoted  at  5  cents  under  the  even  $10  mark. 
For  example,  electric  vacuum  cleaners  are  usually  priced  at  $10 
intervals  from  $39.95  to  $79.95.  Washing  machines  show  the  same 
general  pattern  but  the  range  extends  materially  above  the  $79.95 
level. 

As  in  the  case  of  conventional  price  endings  for  apparel,  this  practice 
is  largely  the  outgrowth  of  manufacturers'  and  distributors'  appraisal 
of  consumer  psychology.  It  is  generally  contended  by  these  trades 
that  inter  ediate  price  levels  are  less  satisfactory  in  stimulating  sales. 
Thus,  if  the  cost  of  producing  and  distributing  a  certain  vacuum 
cleaner  warranted  a  price  of  $61,  it  would  probably  be  marked  at 
$59.95;  similarly,  if  its  cost  indicated  a  retail  price  of  $57  it  would  still 
sell  much  better  at  $59.95.  The  uniformity  with  which  this  practice 
is  observed  illustrates  at  least  that  these  industries  are  convinced  of 
the  validity  of  their  interpretation  of  the  consumer's  reaction. 

Radios. — The  more  common  retail  list  prices  for  radios  follow: 
$12.95,  $17.95,  $24.95,  $29.95,  $39.95,  $49.95,  $59.95,  $69.95,  $79.95, 
$89.95,  and  $129.95. 

Recently  a  small  portable  radio  designed  to  retail  at  $9.95  has  been 
introduced  by  many  manufacturers. 

Refrigerators. — There  is  also  some  evidence  of  the  maintenance  of 
price  lines  for  electric  refrigerators.  In  this  case,  however,  there  is 
somewhat  more  variation  both  as  between  different  makes  and  at 
different  periods  of  time.  Table  21  compares  the  retail  list  prices  for 
the  1938  models  of  nine  nationally  advertised  refrigerators.  (See  p. 
162  supra.) 


250  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

THE    CASH    DISCOUNT    IN    THE    APPAREL    MARKET 

It  has  been  pointed  out  in  chapter  III  of  this  study  (see  p.  74 
supra)  that  wholesale  price  lines  for  apparel,  and  particularly  for 
women's  apparel,  should  be  interpreted  in  the  light  of  the  standard 
so-called  cash  discount.  For  most  lines  of  women's  apparel,  manu- 
facturers regularly  grant  a  discount  of  8/10  EOM  off  the  accepted 
price  line.^ 

An  indication  of  the  extent  to  which  this  discount  is  actually  ob- 
served for  different  kinds  of  goods  has  been  obtained  from  data 
published  by  the  National  Retail  Dry  Goods  Association.®  According 
to  the  data  compiled,  the  8/10  EOM  terms  are  being  granted  on  the 
following  items  of  women's,  misses',  and  girls'  clothing: 

(1)  Neckwear  and  scarfs. 

(2)  Millinery. 

(3)  Corsets  and  brassieres. 

(4)  Sdk  and  muslin  underwear  and  slips. 

(5)  Negligees  and  robes. 

(6)  Coats  and  suits. 

(7)  Dresses. 

(8)  Blouses  and  sportswear. 

(9)  Girls'  wear. 

(10)  Aprons,  housedresses,  and  uniforms. 

(11)  Furs. 

Although  this  allowance  is  usually  called  a  cash  discount  it  is  in 
reality  a  combination  cash  and  trade  discount.  This  interpretation 
is  indicated  both  by  its  size,  which  is  unusually  high  for  a  strictly  cash 
discount,  and  also  by  the  fact  that  failure  to  pay  by  the  date  stipulated 
does  not  usually  entail  the  loss  of  the  entire  discount.  Instead,  if 
payment  is  delayed,  the  terms  are  usually  changed  to  7/10/60.^  This 
is  equivalent  to  charging  interest  at  the  rate  of  6  percent  per  annum 
for  the  additional  60  days  allowed. 

As  in  the  case  of  the  price  lines  themselves  this  discount  largely 
represents  the  crystallization  of  business  custom.  It  was,  however, 
definitely  formalized  about  20  years  ago  by  a  conference  of  retailers 
and  manufacturers.  Later  (about  1925)  the  relative  bargaining 
power  of  the  retailers  seems  to  have  increased,  with  the  result  that 
the  discount  was  increased  to  10/10  EOM  in  a  substantial  portion  of 
the  market,  particularly  in  the  lower  price  lines.  Under  N.  R.  A., 
however,  manufacturers  succeeded  in  restoring  the  terms  of  their  old 
level  of  8/10  EOM;  since  that  time  this  has  been  the  prevailing  prac- 
tice. There  are,  however,  occasional  variations  from  these  terms.  It 
is  understood  that  very  large  buyers  are  sometimes  granted  10/10 
EOM  terms  (representing  an  advantage  of  two  percent.)  Some 
merchants  doing  business  in  small  communities  are  believed  to  receive 

'  I.  6.,  a  discount  of  8  percent  if  payment  is  made  within  10  days  after  the  end  of  the  month  during  which 
the  sale  was  completed. 

'  1937  Departmental  Merchandising  and  Operating  Results  of  Department  and  Specialty  Stores,  pub- 
lished by  the  Controllers'  Congress  of"^°  National  Retail  Dry  Goods  Association.  These  figures  show  the 
typical  performance  figure  in  pach  of  toe  separate  departments  for  the  items  listed.  Cash  discounts  from 
which  any  "loading"  discounts  had  oftfln  eliminated  weio  expressed  in  the  National  Retail  Dry  Goods 
Association  report  as  a  percentage  of  sal*»  In  order  to  calculate  the  cash  discount  as  a  percentage  of  cost 
(the  flsure  to  which  the  S-percent  discount  is  applied),  the  "typical"  figures  for  both  the  cumulative  mark- 
ons  and  mark-downs  harl  to  be  considerftd.  since  each  percentage  represents  the  typical  performance 
rather  than  the  actual  performance  of  any  slmrle  store. 

'  I.  e.,  a  discount  of  7  percent  if  payment  is  made  within  10  days  of  the  expiration  of  a  60-day  period. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER  251 

a  discount  of  only  3  percent.  In  this  way  changes  in  discount  impart 
a  limited  degree  of  flexibility  to  conventional  price  lines. 

The  question  may  be  raised  as  to  whether  a  discount  so  uniformly 
granted  has  any  real  significance  in  the  market  other  than  that  implied 
in  an  equivalent  reduction  in  the  nominal  price  lines.  There  is  some 
evidence,  however,  that  there  is  a  difference  in  the  ultimate  result, 
particularly  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  consumer.  It  is  standard 
bookkeeping  practice  in  many  department  stores  to  apply  this  discount 
to  the  expenses  of  the  "front"  office  rather  than  to  the  credit  of  the 
specific  department  involved.*  If  a  buyer  should,  for  any  reason,  fail 
to  obtain  the  standard  discount,  and  if  office  procedure  is  based  upon 
the  practice  just  mentioned,  it  is  common  to  "load"  the  buyer's  cost. 
For  example,  assume  that  the  terms  received  on  a  $10.75  dress  are  only 
6/10  EOM.  In  such  a  case  the  dress  would  be  charged  to  the  depart- 
ment at  $10.98  and  the  difference  credited  to  the  "front"  office.^ 

This  practice  in  turn  influences  the  retail  selling  price.  The  operat- 
ing results  of  each  department  are  computed  upon  the  basis  of  whole- 
sale price  level.  Consequently,  it  becomes  incumbent  upon  the  buyer 
to  adjust  his  mark-up  accordingly,  if  the  department  is  to  show  an 
adequate   operating   profit. 

Opinions  as  to  the  actual  significance  of  this  situation  differ.  It  is 
contended  on  the  one  hand  that  it  results  in  a  higher  price  to  the  con- 
sumer for  the  commodities  affected  because  of  the  pressure  upon  the 
buyer  to  show  a  profit  based  upon  a  fictitious  cost.  It  is  suggested  on 
the  other  hand  that,  if  this  practice  did  not  prevail,  the  result  would  be 
much  the  same  because  larger  operating  profits  would  be  required 
from  the  individual  departments  in  order  to  defray  necessary  adminis- 
trative expenses.  Perhaps  what  really  happens  is  that  retail  prices 
in  the  departments  aft'ected  by  this  practice  arc  somewhat  higher  than 
they  would  otherwise  be,  while  prices  in  other  departments  are  corre- 
spondingly lower.  In  any  event  the  situation  is  significant  as  an  illus- 
tration of  the  manner  in  which  retail  price  levels  may  be  affected  by 
business  convention. 

*  Recoutlv,  however,  thereseenis  to  be  some  trend  iu  the  opposite  direction. 
«.|10.75  loss  6  percent  equals  $10.10.    .$10.98  less  8  percent  equals  $10.10. 


APPENDIX  III 
Statistical  data  supporting  charts 


Sensitive  and  insensitive  prices 

11926  =  100] 

(Chart  I  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  24) 

INDEXES  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICES  OF  SULFUR,  CRUDE 


Rela- 
tive 

Jan- 
uary 

Feb- 
ruary 

March 

April 

May 

June 

July 

Au- 
gust 

Sep- 
tem- 
ber 

Octo- 
ber 

No- 
vem- 
ber 

De- 
cem- 
ber 

Year 

1926... 
1927... 
1928... 
1929... 
1930... 
1931... 
1932... 
1933... 
1931... 
1935... 
1930... 
1937... 
1938... 
1939 

93 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
87 

3 

8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
9 

93.3 

98.8 
98.8 
98  8 
9S.8 
98.8 
98.8 
98.8 
98.8 
98.8 
98.8 
98.8 
98.8 
87.9 

96 
98 

98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
9S 
98 
98 
87 

1 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
9 

86 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
87 

4 
8 
8 

8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
9 

104 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
93 
98 
87 

3 

8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
9 

104 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
93 
98 
98 
98 
98 
87 

3 

8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 

q 

104 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
87 

3 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
9 

104 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 

3 

8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 

98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 

8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 

98 
98 
9S 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
90 

8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
1 

98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
87 

8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
9 

98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
87 

8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
8 
9 

100 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
98 
96 

0' 
» 
8 

8 
8 
8 
S- 
8 
8 

a 

8 

a 

INDEXES  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICES  OF  BRICK:  LIGHT  COLORED  FRONT,  GOOD  GRADE 


1920... 

103.8 

103.8 

103.8 

101.1 

101.1 

101.1 

98.4 

98.4 

98.4 

98.4 

95.7 

95.7 

100.0 

1927... 

93.0 

93.0 

93.0 

93.0 

93.0 

93.0 

93.0 

93.0 

93.0 

93.0 

93.0 

95.7 

93.  a 

1928... 

93.0 

90.3 

87.6 

87.6 

87  6 

87.6 

84.9 

87.6 

84.9 

84.9 

84.9 

84.9 

87.2 

1929... 

84.9 

84.9 

84.9 

84.9 

84.9 

84.9 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

83.6 

1930... 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

1931... 

82.2 

79.5 

79.5 

79.5 

79.5 

79.5 

79.5 

79.5 

79.5 

76.9 

76.9 

76.0 

79.  a 

1932... 

76.2 

76. 9 

76.9 

76.9 

75.8 

74.2 

72.2 

74.2 

74.2 

74.2 

74.2 

74.2 

75.1 

1933... 

74.2 

74.2 

74.2 

74.2 

74.2 

74.2 

76.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

82.2 

77.7 

1934... 

83.9 

84.9 

87.0 

88.0 

89.0 

89.0 

89.0 

89.0 

89.0 

89.0 

89.0 

89.0 

88.0 

1935... 

89.0 

89.0 

89.0 

89.0 

89.0 

89.0 

89.0 

89.0 

84.9 

83.6 

83.6 

85.8 

87.5 

1936... 

80.2 

80.2 

82.4 

82.9 

81.6 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

84.9 

86.0 

82.8 

1937... 

89.3 

94.4 

94.4 

94.4 

94.4 

94.4 

94.4 

94.4 

94.4 

87.6 

84.9 

84.9 

91.  a 

1938... 

84.9 

84.9 

84.9 

84.9 

87.1 

87.6 

87.6 

87.6 

89.0 

89.7 

90.3 

90.3 

87.4 

1939... 

90.3 

90.3 

90.3 

90.3 

90.3 

90.3 

90.3 

INDEXBS  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICES  OF  WHEAT,  NO.  2, 

HARD 

1926... 

120.8 

115.3 

106.6 

107.4 

104.5 

102.7 

91.7 

83.1 

89.3 

92.5 

91.8 

91.8 

100.  a 

1027... 

92.0 

90.7 

88.7 

87.4 

95.4 

99.4 

93.6 

93.5 

88.4 

89.5 

90.1 

91.1 

91.7 

1928... 

93  3 

92.3 

96.5 

103.5 

109  5 

103.4 

86.0 

73.3 

72.9 

76.5 

76.4 

76.1 

88.5 

1929... 

77.4 

80.3 

78.6 

74.6 

68.4 

69.8 

85.5 

82.2 

82.9 

82.1 

78.9 

83.0 

78.  a 

1930... 

79.4 

74.4 

68.0 

68.0 

86.4 

62.6 

54.7 

55.0 

52.9 

50.7 

46.2 

47.6 

60.1 

1931... 

46.7 

46.7 

47.3 

49.0 

49.1 

44.5 

31.3 

29.7 

30.7 

33.3 

40.9 

37.3 

40.5 

1932... 

36.6 

37.1 

34.6 

36.6 

36.8 

30.3 

31.2 

32.7 

32.6 

30.6 

29.0 

28.3 

33.0 

1933... 

28.8 

29.5 

32.8 

40.3 

47.6 

53.0 

66.5 

59.3 

58.7 

64.8 

56.1 

54.2 

4a  4 

1934... 

56  5 

56.5 

54.8 

51.1 

.S5.  1 

61.6 

63  5 

71.3 

71.5 

68.2 

68.2 

70.3 

62.3 

1935... 

67.3 

67.2 

04.5 

68.7 

66.7 

59.3 

64.8 

69.3 

76.5 

79.6 

74.1 

74.4 

69.5 

1936... 

74.5 

72.5 

71.0 

67.8 

61.5 

63.5 

74.8 

81.2 

80.4 

81.6 

81.5 

89.5 

75.1 

1937... 

92.7 

91.  1 

92.9 

91.5 

88.6 

81.8 

82.1 

73.5 

73.8 

69.1 

63.1 

65.2 

80.3 

1938... 

69.0 

66.8 

61.2 

56.3 

52  0 

54.5 

47.0 

43.9 

43.3 

43.0 

42.8 

45.5 

61. » 

1939  .. 

47.2 

46.3 

45.8 

46.4 

50.8 

49.2 

44.6 

- 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 
252 


CONCENTRATION  01'  ECONOMIC  POAVER 

Wholesale  prices  of  selected  commodities 

[1926=100] 

(Chart  II  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  25) 

EGGS,  FIRSTS,  NEW  YORK 


253 


Year 

Janu- 
ary 

Febru- 
ary 

March 

April 

May 

June 

July 

Au- 
gust 

Sep- 
tem- 
ber 

Octo- 
ber 

No- 
vem- 
ber 

De- 
cem- 
ber 

Yearly 
aver- 
age 

1926... 

107.8 

86.9 

81.1 

89.2 

86.0 

84.8 

82.3 

88.3 

106.2 

113.6 

140.4 

135.  0 

100.0 

1927... 

117.8 

89.8 

70.5 

69.1 

65  8 

65.1 

69.6 

79.0 

96.3 

111.1 

122.6 

127.5 

89.9 

1928... 

126.4 

91.2 

80.4 

79.8 

83.5 

82.8 

85.0 

88.1 

92.8 

91.2 

103.0 

102.8 

92.6 

1929... 

102.2 

115.5 

92.0 

78.2 

87.5 

86.0 

91.1 

97.0 

102.0 

111.0 

135.7 

142.1 

103.  5 

1930... 

118.2 

98.8 

72.3 

75.5 

65.6 

68.4 

62.9 

70.2 

70.6 

74.4 

87.2 

80.7 

78.2 

1931... 

68.0 

56.6 

61.5 

5Q.  6 

53.1 

52.2 

56.6 

62.6 

67.8 

67.9 

80.0 

75.0 

63.2 

1932... 

52.4 

48.4 

39.4 

39.7 

41.2 

39.7 

42.2 

48.8 

58.0 

67.2 

86.7 

88.3 

54.3 

1933... 

64.3 

38.8 

38.3 

37.7 

39.6 

37.4 

43.0 

39.9 

49.9 

56.5 

72.3 

60.5 

48.4 

1934... 

62.4 

51.3 

49.7 

46.9 

46.1 

45.7 

46.9 

58.4 

62.1 

66.5 

77.4 

74.7 

57.2 

1935... 

83.6 

84.4 

60.2 

67.5 

70.5 

68.0 

68.6 

72.9 

76.0 

75.9 

82.4 

75.9 

73.9 

1936. -- 

68.1 

85.3 

58.9 

57.5 

60.7 

62.0 

63.8 

66.6 

69.3 

76.1 

90.7 

90.8 

70.8 

1937... 

70.2 

63.7 

65.1 

63.4 

57.9 

57.9 

59.9 

59.6 

65.6 

66.3 

73.3 

71.2 

64.5 

1938... 

63.0 

52.0 

50.4 

50.  8 

58.8 

57.9 

60.2 

62.2 

70.9 

74.9 

81.6 

78.1 

63.4 

1939... 

55.2 

49.8 

49.1 

48.4 

46.2 

45.5 

45.7 

COTTON  GOODS 


1926... 

107.5 

106.6 

104.9 

103.5 

101.0 

98.6 

98.1 

99.0 

99.4 

96.2 

93.7 

91.8 

100.0 

1927... 

90.1 

90.7 

91.  i 

90.9 

92.9 

94.5 

95.6 

100.1 

106.8 

106.2 

104.3 

102.6 

97.1 

1928... 

101.3 

100.1 

99.7 

99.6 

100.7 

100.5 

101.5 

100.7 

99.2 

99.9 

100.5 

100.9 

100.4 

1929... 

100.4 

99.8 

100.6 

99.4 

98.5 

97.8 

98.2 

98.2 

98.4 

98.5 

97.4 

96.2 

98.8 

1930... 

94.7 

92.8 

90.3 

89.6 

89.0 

87.2 

83.9 

81.1 

78.6 

77.0 

77.5 

75.6 

84.7 

1931. ._ 

73.5 

73.1 

72.4 

71.4 

69.2 

67.6 

66.8 

64.0 

61.5 

59.7 

58.1 

56.4 

66.1 

1932... 

55.8 

56.4 

56.2 

55.1 

52.9 

51.0 

50.0 

52.6 

57.9 

56.2 

53.6 

51.7 

54.0 

1933... 

50.1 

49.1 

50.0 

50.7 

57.9 

67.1 

80.2 

93.5 

91.3 

88.8 

80.0 

85.5 

71.2 

1934... 

86.5 

8S.6 

89.1 

88.2 

86.  3 

86.0 

8?.  1 

86.4 

87.8 

86.6 

84.4 

84.3 

86.5 

1935... 

84.1 

83.3 

82.4 

SI. 8 

82.7 

82.5 

82.0 

82.5 

83.2 

84.6 

80.8 

86.0 

83.4 

19.36... 

80.4 

78.1 

77.1 

76.2 

75.5 

75.4 

78.7 

79.5 

80.0 

82.0 

85.5 

90.3 

80.3 

1937... 

SI.  9 

91.3 

94.0 

95.1 

92.6 

89.7 

86.8 

82.2 

76.8 

73.1 

70.5 

68.7 

84.3 

1938... 

68.2 

67.6 

67.6 

65.7 

65.0 

63.9 

65.1 

C4.4 

64.1 

64.6 

65.1 

64.6 

65.4 

1939... 

64.3 

63.7 

63.7 

63.4 

63.3 

64.1 

65.1 

DOMESTIC  RAYON 


1926... 

110.5 

110.5 

110.5 

110.5 

110.5 

110.5 

91.2 

91.2 

91.2 

91.2 

91.2 

91.2 

100.0 

1927... 

80.1 

80.1 

81.2 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82  9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.3 

1928... 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

82.9 

1929... 

82.9 

80.1 

71.8 

71.8 

71.8 

69.8 

63.6 

63.6 

63.6 

63.6 

63.6 

63.6 

68.9 

1930... 

63.6 

63.6 

63.6 

63.6 

63.6 

63.6 

59.1 

52.5 

52.5 

52.5 

52.5 

62.5 

68.5 

1931... 

47.0 

41.4 

41.4 

41.4 

41.4 

41.4 

41.4 

41.4 

41.4 

41.4 

41.4 

41.4 

41.9 

1932... 

41.4 

41.4 

41.4 

41.4 

40.3 

35.9 

31.8 

30.9 

33.2 

33.2 

33.2 

33.2 

36.5 

1933... 

33.2 

33.2 

33.2 

27.6 

30.4 

31.8 

34.5 

35.9 

35.9 

35.9 

35.9 

35.9 

33.6 

1934... 

35.9 

35.9 

35.9 

35.9 

31.9 

30.4 

30.4 

30.4 

30.4 

30.4 

30.4 

31.2 

32.4 

1935... 

33.2 

33.2 

3.3.2 

32.1 

30.4 

30.4 

30.4 

31.2 

31.5 

31.5 

31.5 

31.5 

31.7 

1936... 

31.5 

31.5 

31.5 

31.5 

31.5 

31.8 

33.2 

33.2 

33.2 

33.2 

33.2 

33.2 

32.4 

1937... 

33.2 

33.2 

33.2 

34.8 

34.8 

34.8 

34.8 

34.8 

34.8 

34.8 

34.8 

34.8 

34.4 

1938... 

33.0 

29.8 

29.8 

29.8 

28.7 

27.1 

27.1 

28.2 

28.2 

28.2 

28.2 

28.2 

28.9 

1939... 

28.2 

28.2 

28.2 

28.2 

28.2 

28.2 

28.2 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


254 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Wholesale  prices  of  selected  commodities — Continued 

[1926=100] 

(Chart  III  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  26) 

PHOSPHATE  ROCK 


Year 

Janu- 
ary 

Feb- 
ruary 

March 

April 

May 

June 

July 

Au- 
gust 

Sep- 
tem- 
ber 

Octo- 
ber 

No- 
vem- 
ber 

De- 
cem- 
ber 

i926    

94.6 
95.5 
95.5 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
90.8 
108.3 
58.9 
58.9 
58.9 
60.5 

99.5 
95.6 
95.6 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
90.8 
108.3 
58.9 
58.9 
58.9 
60.5 

103.6 

95.5 
95.5 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
90.8 
108.3 
58.9 
58.9 
58.9 
60.5 

101.1 
95.5 
95.5 

98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
90.8 
108.3 
58.9 
58.9 
58.9 
60.5 

100.3 
95.5 
95.5 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
90.8 

108.3 
58.9 
58.9 
58.9 
60.5 

100.3 
95.5 
95.5 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
93.3 

108.3 
58.9 
58.9 
58.9 
60.5 

100.3 

95.5 
95.5 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
103.5 
108.3 
58.9 
58.9 
58.9 
60.5 

100.3 
95.5 
97.9 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
95.9 
103.5 
108.3 
58.9 
58.9 
58.9 

100.3 
95.5 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
87.9 
103.5 
108.3 
58.9 
58.9 
58.9 

100.3 
95.5 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
89.2 
103.5 
108.3 
58.9 
58.9 
58.9 

100.3 
95.5 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
89.2 
103.5 
108.3 
58  9 
58.9 
58.9 

100.3 

1927.-. 

95.5 

1928       

98.7 

1929    

98.7 

1930 

98.7 

1931           

98.7 

1932    

98.7 

1933 

89.2 

1934 

104.4 

1935    

61.3 

1936 

58.9 

1937           .      . 

58.9 

1938    

59.2 

1939 

ANTHRACITE 


1926. -.- 

1927 

113.7 
99.1 
94.8 
91.6 
91.2 
88.9 
94.8 

•88.7 
81.6 
82.3 
82.3 
81.6 
80.1 
80.3 

102.0 
98.9 
95.3 
91.6 
91.2 
88.9 
94.8 
88.7 
81.2 
82.3 
82.6 
81.6 
79.8 
79.9 

101.2 
96.8 
94.8 
91.4 
91.2 
88.4 
89.9 
88.3 
81.2 
81.1 
82.  5 
77.8 
79.3 
79.4 

98.1 
93.8 
89.7 
88.1 
90.2 
86.4 
85.7 
81.4 
78.1 
75.5 
80.0 
72.4 
76.0 
71.7 

97.6 
93.6 
89.0 
67.4' 
86.7 
87.5 
85.6 
78.5 
75.7 
73.0 
7fi.  6 
74.2 
73.8 
75.3 

97.3 
94.8 
90.4 
88.1 
85.8 
88.8 
85.3 
76.8 
76.9 
74.0 
77.0 
74.5 
74.5 
70.5 

97.4 
95.2 
90.5 
89.1 
86.5 
90.8 
84.5 
77.9 
78.6 
77.0 
78.5 
76.6 
76.2 
72.6 

98.1 
95.7 
90.3 
90.0 
88.0 
92.2 
86.0 
79.2 
79.9 
78.6 
79  1 
76.8 
77.9 

98.4 
97.0 
91.2 
90.6 
89.1 
94.3 
87.7 
82.0 
81.3 
80.fi 
80,6 
78.7 
79.1 

98.4 
96.9 
91.2 
91.2 
89.7 
94.2 
88.7 
81.8 
82.0 
82.  S 
81.8 
78.8 
79.1 

98.8 
96.9 
91.2 
91.2 
89.6 
94.2 
88.8 
81.8 
82.1 
83.0 
82.4 
79.8 
80.1 

98.8 
96.8 

1928      .... 

91.2 

1929 

1930 

91.2 
89.6 

1931 

94.8 

1932      

88.7 

1933 

81.5 

1934.. 

82.3 

1935 

82.9 

1936 

82.3 

1937 

80.0 

1938 

80.1 

1939 

POTATOES 
(Wliits,  good  to  choice,  bulk) 


Year 

Jan- 
uary 

Feb- 
ruary 

March 

April 

May 

Jane 

July 

Au- 
gust 

Sep- 
tem- 
ber 

Octo- 
ber 

No- 
vem- 
ber 

De- 
cem- 
ber 

Yearly 
aver- 
age 

1926... 

134.0 

123.2 

132.4 

151.8 

112.6 

105.7 

67.0 

74.0 

75.9 

72.2 

77.8 

75.1 

100.0 

1927... 

76.8 

77.8 

62.7 

86.3 

119.5 

122.6 

70.9 

66.0 

64.3 

58.3 

58.6 

55.  6 

76.6 

1928... 

56.6 

65.8 

86.1 

65.1 

50.3 

44.8 

30.0 

2G.  6 

30.5 

27.4 

28.2 

31.9 

44.9 

1929... 

34.5 

28.8 

26.8 

23.4 

25.3 

26.3 

69.5 

84.0 

83.4 

79.7 

75.3 

77.0 

53.3 

1930... 

82.6 

81.3 

78.6 

92.6 

89.2 

88.8 

52.6 

63.3 

69.9 

59.3 

51.0 

46.8 

70  9 

1931... 

48.5 

46.5 

47.6 

49.2 

41.9 

52.4 

45.6 

39.6 

31.5 

25.1 

20.1 

27.9 

40.1 

1932... 

27.2 

25.9 

27.8 

27.2 

27.9 

37.0 

31.3 

24.4 

23.1 

21.8 

22.1 

24.4 

26.6 

1933... 

24.5 

25.0 

25.9 

25.3 

24.5 

53.9 

91.3 

83.8 

52.1 

40.5 

42.3 

42.7 

44.2 

1934... 

55.1 

59.5 

50.8 

45.0 

33.9 

35.5 

41.5 

45.2 

30.0 

27.8 

26.0 

20.0 

40.4 

1935... 

27.4 

25.2 

22.1 

27.4 

21.9 

33.0 

45.6 

33.8 

30.2 

28.0 

36.1 

38.0 

31.0 

1936... 

38.6 

42.7 

39.5 

45.0 

60.4 

88.9 

77.8 

78.2 

72.2 

68.2 

70.9 

73.8 

63.6 

1937... 

88.8 

94.6 

87.3 

68.6 

64.3 

50.0 

50.4 

38.7 

31.7 

31.9 

35.1 

36.3 

56.2 

1938... 

33.9 

34.6 

33.4 

38.3 

45.1 

53.1 

33.8 

30.0 

29.6 

29.7 

36.0 

36.4 

36.2 

1939 

41.3 

41.4 

40.0 

39.9 

41.8 

61.9 

41.1 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


255 


iVholesale  prices  of  selected  commodities — Continued 

POTASH  SALTS 
[1926-28=100] 


Month 


January- 
February. 

March 

April. 

May 

June 

July 

August 

September 
October... 
November 
December. 


1929 


101.0 
101.0 
101.0 
101.0 
92.8 
95.0 
95.8 
96.9 
97.9 
98.9 
100.0 
102.0 


1930 


102.0 
102.0 
103.2 
103.2 
94.0 
96.0 
97.0 
98.0 
99.0 
100.0 
101.0 
103.2 


1931 


103.2 
103.2 
103.2 
103.2 
91.8 
95.9 
97.0 
98.0 
99.0 
100.0 
101.0 
103.2 


1932 


103.2 
103.2 
103.2 
103.2 
90.5 
95.8 
96.8 
97.8 
98.8 
99.8 
100.9 
102.8 


1933 


102.8 
102.8 
102.8 
102.8 
90.2 
90.2 
90.2 
90.2 
90.2 
96.0 
96.0 
96,0 


1934 


101.0 
101.0 
101.0 
101.0 
80.0 
80.0 
81.1 
59.6 
59.6 
63.5 
63.5 
63.5 


1935 


63.5 
63.5 
63.6 
63.6 
61.6 
61.5 
56.4 
60.3 
60.3 
64.2 
64.2 
64.2 


1936 


64.2 
64.2 
64.2 
64.2 
64.2 
64.2 
62.3 
67.3 
67.3 
69.3 
69.3 
70.7 


1937 


70.7 
70.7 
70.7 
70.7 
70.7 
66.4 
71.9 
71.9 
71.9 
75.5 
75.5 
75.5 


1938 


76.6 
75.6 
75.5 
75.6 
75.6 
66.6 
71.9 
71.9 
71.9 
76.7 


Source:  National  Fertilizer  Association. 


Average  factory  price  of  electric  refrigerators 

[1928  =  100] 


Year — 

1928 100.0 

1929 

1930 

1931 

1932 


Source:  National  Electrical  Manufacturers  Association 


Index 

Year — 

00.0 

1933 

80.8 

1934 

79.8 

1935 

77.5 

1936 

61.0 

Associa 

1937 

tion. 

Index 
50.  1 
50.8 
46.  9 
48.6 
51.2 


Changes  in  average  wholesale  price  and  quantity  available  for  consumption  for  11 J 

commodities,  1929-33 


[Chart  IV  based  on 

the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p. 

39] 

Percent  change 

Commodities 

Percent  change 

Commodities 

Average 
price 

Amount 
available 

for  con- 
sumption 

Average 
price 

Amount 
available 

for  con- 
sumption 

NoDfiuiablfc  goods. 

Corn 

•-37 

•-20 

•-28 

-57 

-ei 

-55 

-53 

•-32 

•-44 

-39 

-42 

•-58 

•-34 

-53 

-47 

-7 

-17 

•-13 

-51 

-56 

-57 

-15 

•-13 

-51 

-45 

-9 
-9 

•-3 

•-27 
•+1 
+28 

-2 
•+6 

-1 

-4 
-62 
•+4 

-4 

-l 

•+7 
•+1 
-16 
-13 
•-15 
•+6 
•+4 
+3 

-6 
•-6 
-13 

+2 

-31 
-37 

Nondurable  goods— Con. 
Coke    

-6 

-27 
-14 
-TA 
-14 
0 
-24 
-11 
-28 
-28 
-56 
-30 
-53 
-34 
-53 
-55 
-16 

0 

-8 

-9 

-12 

•-33 

-21 
-6 
-2 

-43 

-60 

Oats    .  .. 

Fuel  oil 

—30 

Wheal 

Oasoliui'* 

+3 

Steers 

-15 

Hops 

Cans,  sanitary 

—2 

Poultry,  live      .  . 

Sulfuric  acid.. 

Alcohol,  denatured 

Sodium  ash 

-34 

Eggs 

-42 

Apples. 

—7 

Oranges 

Castor  oil 

-39 

Milk. .. 

Olycerine 

Ammonia  (sulfate) 

Superphosphate 

Tankage     .     .  

—7 

Tobacco 

+53 

Bean<;,  dried 1. 

Potatoes,  white 

-37 
-39 

Butter.    . 

Fertilizers,  mixed 

Bran  and  middlings 

Cottonseed  meal 

Poiboard 

-46 

Cheese 

—31 

Brpad 

-3 

Flour,  wheat 

-8 

Rice 

Beef,  fre.oh 

Wrapping  paper  (ma- 
nila)            

-10 

Pork,  fresh.. 

Soap,  laundry 

-9 

Poultry,  dressed .. 

Cigarettes 

-1 

Sugar: 

Ci<'ats. - 

-2« 

Granulated 

Semidurable  goods: 

Cotton  .         . 

Raw 

•-7 

Vegetable  oil,  coconut.. 
Twine,  binder 

Shoes: 

Children's 

+26 

Coal: 

Men's . 

-6 

Anthracite 

Ladies' 

0 

Bituminous 

Hides,  steer 

-14 

256 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Changes  in  average  wholesale  price  and  quantity  available  for  consumption  for  111 
commodities,  1929-83 — Continued 


Percent  change 

Commodities 

Percent  change 

Commodities 

Average 
price 

Amount 
available 
for  con- 
sumption 

Average 
price 

Amount 
available 
for  con- 
sumption 

Scmidurabie  goods— Con. 

Skins,  goat 

Jycather: 

Calf..  

-32 

-24 
-37 
-41 
-36 
-2 
-7 
-11 
-28 
-34 
-23 

-47 
-47 
-23 
-51 
-67 
-55 
-32 
-18 
-26 
-36 
-22 
-20 
-18 
-26 
-26 
-71 

-18 
-2 

-19 

-18 
-11 
-4 
-58 
-42 
-11 
-40 
+2 
+  1 
-23 

-41 

+4 
+  1 
+64 
-23 
-75 
-14 
-28 
+1 
-37 
+10 
-50 
-37 
-49 
-41 
-27 

-52 
-99 

Durable  goods— Continued. 

Plows... 

Tractors    

Castings,  malleable 

Pipe,  blick  steel 

Structural  steel 

Tinplate  and  terneplate. 

Passenger  cars 

Trucks 

0 
-29 
-25 
-16 
-15 
-17 
-16 
-23 
-61 
-43 
-13 
-27 
-38 
-26 

-19 
-7 
-7 
-6 

-30 
-22 
-20 
-11 
-28 
-28 
-29 

-47 
-21 
-17 
-21 

-01 
-95 
-63 

Kid 

-26 

Sole... 

-76 

Gloves 

-3 

Ovsrcoats  and  topcoats. 
Shirts,  dress 

-64 
—45 

Suits,  men's.. 

Copper,  ingot. 

Leid,  pig 

Tin,  pig                    .     . 

-88 

Print  cloth 

-65 

Sheel  ing,  bleached 

-28 

Cotton  yarn,  carded 

Boilers,  heating 

-21 

Hosiery: 

Radiation 

-76 

Rayon 

Bathtubs... 

-69 

Silk     . 

Brick: 

Common. 

Fire  clay 

Front 

Union  suits,  women's. -. 
Rayon    .  ... 

-82 
-59 

Silk,  raw,  Japan 

Silk  yarn 

-87 

Cement 

-63 

Dress  goods,  woolen 

Overcoating 

Lumber: 

Dougla'  flr 

-53 

Yarn,  wool 

Oak  

-77 

Burlap 

Pine 

-62 

Thread,  cotton.. 

Paint,  outside  white 

Varnish 

Crushed  stone 

Tar,  pine._ 

Carpets                      

-51 
-22 
-19 

Linseed  oil,  raw 

Tires,  balloon 

Stoves,  gas 

Washing     machines, 
electric 

-54 

+8 

Durable  goods: 

Belting,  leather.'. 

Harvester-thresher 

Mattresses 

Davenports 

Paper,  book 

-50 
-67 

-28 

Source:  Percentages  computed  by  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics,  except  those  marked 
furnished  by  the  Bureau  of  Agricultural  Economics. 


which  were 


Farm  products — prices  and  production 

[1926  =  100] 
(Chart  V  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  41) 


Year 

Index  of 

wholesale 

prices ' 

Index  of 
produc- 
tion' 

Year 

Index  of 

wholesale 

prices ' 

Index  of 
produc- 
tion' 

1926 

100.0 
99.4 
lO.'-i.  9 
104.9 
88.3 
64.8 
48.2 

100 
97 

102 
99 
99 

105 
98 

1933 

51.4 
65.3 
78.8 
80.9 
80.4 
08.5 

95 

1927.. 

U'34                     

92 

1928.. 

1935.. _ 

90 

1929 

1936 

93 

1930 

1937 

106 

1931    . 

.1938 

102 

1932.. 

'  Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

'  Source:  Bureau  of  Agricultural  Economics. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


257 


Wholesale  prices  of  SO  basic  commodities,  industrial  production,  and  reciprocals  of 

price  dispersion 

[1929=100] 

WHOLESALE  PRICE  INDEXES  OF  30  BASIC  COMMODITIES 

(Chart  VI  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  44) 


Year 

Jan- 
uary 

Feb- 
ruary 

March 

AprU 

May 

June 

July 

Au- 
gust 

Sep- 
tem- 
ber 

Octo- 
tober 

No- 
vem- 
ber 

De- 
cem- 
ber 

Yearly 

aver- 
age 

1926... 
1927... 
1928... 
1929... 
1930... 
1931... 
1932... 
1933... 
1934... 
1935... 
1936... 
1937... 
1938... 
1939  .. 

117.0 
103.2 
108.5 
101.9 
89.1 
61.9 
46.3 
37.2 
57.4 
71.8 
72.0 
89.9 
68.6 
63.1 

112.6 
104.1 
105.6 
103.4 
88.2 
60.0 
45.1 
36.4 
61.1 
72.0 
71.6 
89.2 
67.1 
62.9 

108.4 
103.7 
105.4 
104.1 
85.7 
61.1 
43.9 
38.4 
61.0 
70.0 
70.8 
92.6 
65.9 
63.3 

106.2 
103.3 
106.3 
101.9 
84.7 
59.1 
41.4 
41.3 
60.6 
70.4 
70.3 
90.4 
63.3 
61.7 

104.6 
102.9 
107.5 
98.4 
80.8 
55.9 
39.0 
51.0 
60.9 
70.8 
67.8 
87.0 
61.7 
62.5 

107.3 
103.2 
105.7 
98.2 
76.4 
55.2 
37.6 
55.9 
61.7 
09. 9 
68.7 
84.6 
60.9 
62.0 

108.1 
103.7 
105.9 
iOl.4 
73.4 
55.3 
38.6 
61.7 
f.2.4 
69.2 
73.2 
86.8 
64.3 
60.3 

106.9 
105.9 
103.9 
101.9 
72.7 
52.6 
42.8 
58.7 
65.9 
70.7 
76.7 
85.0 
03. 3 
59.5 

107.9 
107.3 
104.0 
102.3 
71.2 
50.3 
45.2 
58.0 
67.9 
72.7 
77.8 
&3.4 
63.2 

104.7 
107.0 
102.8 
99.6 
68.8 
49.1 
42.0 
55.3 
66.5 
74.8 
77.8 
76.7 
63.8 

102.4 
106.7 
101.9 
94.3 
66.5 
60.1 
40.3 
55.8 
67.6 
74.1 
81.4 
70.5 
63.8 

102.7 
107.7 
102.0 
91.3 
64.6 
47.1 
38.0 
54.6 
68.9 
73.1 
86.4 
68.1 
63.1 

107.6 
105.4 
105.4 
100.0 
77.0 
55.0 
41.9 
50.7 
63.9 
71.9 
74.8 
84.2 
64.3 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

INDEXES  OF  INDUSTRIAL  PRODUCTION,  ADJUSTED 


Year 

Jan- 
uary 

Feb- 
ruary 

March 

April 

May 

June 

July 

Au- 
gust 

Sep- 
tem- 
ber 

Octo- 
ber 

No- 
vem- 
ber 

De- 
cem- 
ber 

1926 

89 
90 
90 
100 
89 
70 
61 
56 
66 
77 
82 
96 
68 
85 

88 
91 
92 
99 
90 
72 
58 
53 
68 
75 
79 
98 
66 
82 

89 
92 
91 
99 
87 
73 
56 
50 
71 
74 
78 
99 
66 
82 

90 
91 
91 
102 
87 
74 
53 
56 
72 
72 
S5 
99 
65 
77 

89 
92 
91 
103 
86 
73 
50 
66 
72 
71 
85 
99 
64 
77 

91 
90 
91 
105 
82 
70 
50 
77 
71 
72 
87 
96 
65 
82 

91 
89 
92 
104 
78 
69 
49 
84 
64 
72 
91 
96 
70 
85 

92 
89 
92 
102 
76 
66 
50 
77 
61 
73 
91 
98 
74 
86 

93 
87 
95 
102 
76 
64 
56 
71 
60 
76 
92 
93 
77 

93 
86 
97 
99 
74 
61 
56 
64 
62 
SO 
92 
87 
81 

92 
85 
98 
92 
72 
61 
55 
61 
63 
82 
9fi 
7.5 
87 

90 

J927 

86 

1928 

99 

1929.... 

87 

1930 

71 

1931 

1932 : 

62 
66 

1933      

63 

1934 

1935 

72 
87 

1936 

1937 

102 
71 

1938.... 

87 

1939 

Source:  Federal  Reserve  Board. 

RECIPROCALS  OF  INDEXES  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  DISPERSION 


Year 

Jan- 
uary 

Feb- 
ruary 

March 

April 

May 

June 

July 

Au- 
gust 

Sep- 
tem- 
ber 

Octo- 
ber 

No- 
vem- 
ber 

De- 
cem- 
ber 

1928... 

116.1 
103.1 
100.9 
70.0 
41.4 
34.4 
42.7 
75.8 
71.6 
92.3 
63.9 
65.8 

125.8 
105.9 
99.2 
66.4 
39.3 
32.8 
45.7 
76.1 
75.1 
93.4 
60.2 
54.3 

126.9 
92.0 
93.6 
64.3 
39.7 
34.1 
46.4 
69.2 
72.2 
82.0 
59.0 
53.3 

114.8 
91.8 
93.0 
62.3 
39.4 
35.3 
44.8 
71.5 
75.4 
72.5 
56.2 
61.8 

106.6 
94.8 
92.8 
57.1 
36.7 
41.1 
45.2 
71.1 
79.2 
69.8 
54.8 
63.3 

112.6 
97.8 
90.1 
53.2 
36.0 
45.1 
49.7 
73.3 
87.2 
68.6 
54.1 
64.1 

99.9 
90.3 
89.0 
53.2 
39.7 
47.9 
51.7 
72.3 
93.7 
62.1 
54.7 
64.4 

94.5 
89.3 
91.6 
53.0 
40.9 
44.2 
67.9 
66.3 
88.2 
68.6 
64.9 
61.8 

88.0 
92.9 
83.4 
49.7 
42.2 
45.1 
64.9 
64.7 
88.5 
68.7 
56.0 

105.6 
99.2 
81.0 
48.6 
39.6 
43.1 
69.3 
67.4 
94.6 
60.1 
57.1 

113.0 
105.3 
74.5 
48.1 
39.4 
42.9 
59.7 
75.4 
98.6 
63.6 
69.2 

109.8 

1929 . 

102.7 

1930 

72.9 

1931... 

43.7 

1932 

36.6 

1933 

40.6 

1934 

60.1 

1936 

70.4 

1936... 

97.3 

1937 

64.4 

1938 

69.2 

1939 

Source:  Works  Progress  Administration. 

The  measure  of  dispersion  is  the  weighted  average  of  the  deviations  of  the  45  commodity  subgroup  price 
indexes  from  the  all-commodities  index.  The  indexef  were  derived  by  dividing  the  monthly  average  devia- 
tions by  the  average  deviation  in  1929.  •  The  reciprocals  were  obtained  by  dividing  each  monthly  dispersion 
index  into  100. 


258  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Indexes  of  Wholesale  Price  Dispersion  and  Industrial  Production 

[ioa6«=ioo] 

(Chart  VII  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  46) 

INDEXES  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICE  DISPERSION 


Year 

Jan- 
uary 

Feb- 
ruary 

March 

AprU 

May 

June 

July 

Au- 
gust 

Sep- 
tem- 
ber 

Octo- 
ber 

No- 
vem- 
ber 

De- 
cem- 
ber 

1928 

1929... 

86.1 
97.0 
99.1 
142.8 
241.6 
290.5 
234.4 
132.0 
139.8 
108.3 
156.6 
179.1 

79.6 
94.4 
100.8 
150.7 
254.7 
305.0 
219.0 
131.4 
133.2 
107.1 
166.1 
184.3 

78.8 
108.7 
106.8 
155.6 
252.2 
293.3 
215.3 
144.5 
138.5 
121.9 
169.6 
187.5 

87.1 
108.9 
107.6 
160.5 
253.8 
283.2 
223.3 
139.^ 
132.6 
137.9 
178.0 
193.0 

93.8 
105.6 
107.8 
175.1 
272.5 
243.2 
221.4 
140.6 
126.3 
143.2 
182.4 
187.6 

88.8 
102.2 
111.0 
188.1 
277.4 
221.7 
201.4 
136.6 
114.7 
145.7 
186.0 
184.8 

100.1 
110.7 
112.4 
187.8 
252.1 
208.8 
193.4 
138.3 
106.7 
161.0 
182.8 
183.8 

106.8 
112.0 
109.2 
1&8.6 
244.4 
226.4 
172.7 
150.9 
113.4 
170.6 
182.2 
193.2 

113.7 
107.6 
119.9 
201.4 
237.1 
221.7 
154.1 
154.5 
113.0 
170.3 
178.7 
153.5 

94.8 
100.8 
123.4 
206.3 
252.3 
231.8 
168.5 
148.3 
105.7 
166.3 
175.2 
171.1 

88.5 
95.0 
134.2 
208.0 
253.8 
233.2 
167.4 
132.7 
101.4 
157.2 
168.8 

91.1 
97.4 

1930 

137.2 

1931.. 

228  6 

1932    

281  6 

1933.. 

246.4 

1934_ 

166.3 

1935 

142.0 

1936... 

102.8 

1937 

155.4 

1938 

168.  S 

1939 

Source:  Works  Progress  Administration. 

INDEXES  OF  INDUSTRIAL  PRODUCTION,  ADJUSTED 


Year 

Jan- 
uary 

Feb- 
ruary 

March 

April 

May 

June 

July 

Au- 
gust 

Sep- 
tem- 
ber 

Octo- 
ber 

No- 
vem- 
ber 

De- 
cem- 
ber 

1926 

■      89 
90 
90 
100 
89 
70 
61 
55 
66 
77 
82 
96 
68 
85 

88 
91 
92 
99 
90 
72 
58 
.    53 
68 
75 
79 
98 
66 
82 

89 

92 

91 

99 

87. 

73 

66 

50 

71 

74 

78 

99 

66 

82 

90 
91 
91 
102 
87 
74 
63 
56 
72 
72 
85 
99 
66 
77 

89 
92 
91 
103 
86 
73 
50 
66 
72 
71 
86 
99 
64 
77 

91 
90 
91 
105 
82 
70 
50 
77 
71 
72 
87 
96 
65 
82 

91 
89 
92 
104 
78 
69 
49 
84 
64 
72 
91 
96 
70 
85 

92 

■    89 

92 

102 
76 
66 
50 
77 

'61 
73 
91 
98 
74 
86 

93 

87 
96 
102 
76 
64 
56 
71 
60 
76 
92 
93 
77 
93 

93 

86 
97 
99 
74 
61 
56 
64 
62 
80 
92 
87 
81 
101 

92 
85 
98 
92 
72 
61 
55 
61 
63 
82 
96 
75 
87 

90 

1927 

86 

1928 

99 

1929 

1930 

1931 

1932- 

87 
71 
62 
66 

1933    .  . 

63 

1934.. 

1935 

72 
87 

1936 

102 

1937      . 

71 

1938 

87 

1939.... 

Source:  Federal  Reserve  Board. 

Automobile  tires — wholesale  price  and  average  life  of  automobile  tires 
(Chart  VIII  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  66) 


Year 

Price  index  i 
(1926  =  100) 

Tire  life » 
(years) 

Year 

Price  index  ' 
(1926=100) 

Tire  life » 
(years) 

1913 .; 

207.2 
173.1 
155.1 
160.4 
198.0 
229  2 
209.2 
232.5 
179.0 
115.4 
109.6 
92.6 
98.6 

0.805 
.722 
.768 
.762 
.712 
.893 
.933 
1.  281 
1.486 
1.296 
1.608 
1.670 
1.6S1 

1926 

100.0 
74.9 
63.4 
64.5 
51.3 
46.0 
41.1 
42.1 
44.9 
45.7 
47.2 
66.8 
57.7 

1.770 

1914 

1927 

1.665 

1915 

1928      

1.650 

1916 

1929 

1.848 

1917. 

1930 

2.465 

1918 

1931 

2.417 

1919  ..  » 

1932     ..  -. 

2.689 

1920 

1933 

2.427 

1921 

1934 

2.666 

1922. 

1935 

2.725 

1923 

1936 

2.695 

1924 

1937 

»  2. 908 

1925. 

1933 

1  Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

'Source:  Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce,  Rubber  News  Letter. 
'Preliminary. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Retail  prices  of  men's  dress  shirts 
(Chart  IX  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  dppears  on  p.  84) 


259 


Date 

One  na- 
tionally ad- 
vertised 
brand 

Other 
brands  ' 

Date 

One  na- 
tionally ad- 
vertised 
brand 

Other 
brands  * 

December  1929 

$1.95 
1.95 
1.95 

$1.91 
1.55 
1.76 

November  1934  ..    .    . 

$1.95 
2.00 
2.00 

$1.73 

December  1932. 

December  1936 

1.59 

December  1933 

December  1937 

1.61 

'  Unweighted  average. 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


Breakfast  cereals — prices  and  margins 

(Chart  X  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  85) 

[Cents  per  pound] 


Rolled  oats 

Corn  flakes 

Year 

Farm 
value  ' 

Wholesale 
price  ' 

Retail 
price  > 

Farm 
value ' 

Wholesale 
price  > 

Retail 
price ' 

1926... 

2.2 
2.5 
2.7 
2.5 
2.1 
3.4 
1.0 
1.4 
2.3 
2.2 
1.9 
2.3 

6.6 
6.7 
6.6 
6.6 
6.6 
6.0 
5.4 
4.0 
5  3 
5.8 
5.6 
5.7 

9.1 
9.0 
9.0 
8.8 
8.6 
8.0 
7.4 
5.8 
6.8 
7.5 
7.4 
7.5 

2.8 
3.6 
4.0 
4.0 
3.6 
2.2 
1.3 
1.7 
2.8 
3.6 
3.6 
4.4 

13.4 
13.4 
13.4 
13.4 
13.4 
13.4 
13.4 
13.4 
13.0 
12.5 
12.1 
12.6 

21.0 

1927. 

19.8 

1928 _-- 

1929 _ 

18.8 
18.6 

1930  .. 

18.4 

1931 

17  6 

1932 

16.8 

1933 

16.8 

1934 -. 

16.8 

1935 

1936        

16.6 
16  2 

1937 

15.8 

>  Source:  Bureau  of  Agricultural  Economics. 
2  Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

Wholesale  prices  of  selected  foods  (■products  classified  into  4  guartiles  according  to 

consumer  buying  habits)  ' 

[1929  =  100] 
(Chart  XI  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  87) 
FIRST  QUARTILE 


Years 

Month 

1926 

1927 

1928 

1629 

1930 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936 

1937 

19.38 

1939 

January 

103.8 

92.8 

101.0 

98.0 

96.1 

74.4 

61.7 

49.0 

67.0 

79.2 

78.6 

80.2 

72.1 

68.4 

February 

102.7 

91.0 

102.5 

97.9 

9.5.9 

70.8 

59.8 

48.2 

68.3 

79.4 

76.9 

80.2 

71.6 

67.5 

March 

101.6 

90.0 

103.5 

98.9 

94.5 

71.6 

58.6 

49.9 

69.5 

79.6 

75.6 

81.1 

71.6 

67.5 

April 

101.0 

90.5 

104.2 

100.1 

93.7 

70.2 

57.2 

51.7 

69.9 

81.1 

76.5 

83.8 

71.4 

67.6 

May 

102.1 

92.6 

105.0 

100.8 

90.7 

69.5 

55.7 

56.1 

71.1 

81.4 

75.2 

84.4 

70.8 

68.2 

June 

99.9 

92.8 

102.0 

99.1 

89.4 

67.5 

55.1 

52.7 

71.4 

81.0 

74.4 

83.8 

70.5 

66.8 

July 

99.6 

93.0 

102.1 

102.1 

85.0 

67.0 

55.1 

56.4 

72  6 

79.8 

76.8 

84.1 

70.9 

65.8 

August 

97.8 

92.5 

100.6 

103.0 

83.8 

66.2 

55.0 

55.9 

76.1 

80.4 

81.1 

82.5 

68.8 

September.. 

96.2 

94.5 

102.9 

102.8 

81.8 

65.4 

55.2 

63.7 

79.0 

81.2 

82.0 

81.4 

69.1 

October 

94.8 

94.4 

100.9 

100.6 

78.9 

63.1 

5b.  4 

65.0 

78.4 

82.0 

79.9 

77.9 

68.2 

November... 

93.5 

97.7 

98.3 

98.7 

75.8 

64.0 

51.3 

66.8 

78.1 

80.1 

78.8 

72.3 

68.1 

December... 

92.9 

99.3 

96.6 

97.7 

74.6 

62.4 

49.3 

66.7 

78.4 

80.1 

78.9 

72.0 

68.2 

Vearly  aver- 

age  

98.8 

96.2 

101.7 

100.0 

86.6 

67.6 

55.6 

58.7 

73.3 

80.4 

77.9 

80.2 

70.1 

'  For  first  quartile,  brand  names  were  least  significant  to  consumer,  and  progressively  more  significant 
in  each  succeeding  quartile. 

Data  based  upon  sample  study  of  consumer  buying  habits  designed  to  determine  relative  weight  given 
to  brand  names  by  consumers  in  purchasing  different  commodities.  The  products  covered  were  ranked 
according  to  the  importance  of  brand  names  in  their  respective  markets,  and  then  grouped  into  iquartiles 
on  the  basis  of  these  ranks.  Unweighted  averages  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  wholesale  prices  for  each 
■quartile  were  then  computed. 


260 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Wholesale  prices  of  selected  foods  (products  classified  into  4  quartiles  according  to^ 
consumer  buying  habits) — Continued 

[1929=100] 
SECOND  QUARTILE 


Years 

Month 

1926 

1927 

1928 

1929 

1930 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936 

1937 

1938 

1939 

January 

98.6 

93.0 

104.0 

99.5 

96.0 

78.0 

62.3 

57.0 

68.1 

85.6 

77.2 

89.5 

74.4 

66.5 

February 

96.9 

94.7 

105.0 

99.1 

95.4 

76.3 

61.6 

56.3 

70.3 

88.2 

76.4 

89.5 

72.3 

65.8 

March. _ 

94.4 

94.5 

105.0 

100.1 

94.1 

76.6 

60.8 

57.4 

72.9 

88.3 

75.6 

90.5 

71.4 

65.5 

April... 

94.7 

95.3 

105.2 

99.4 

92.4 

75.6 

59.6 

59.2 

72.3 

87.8 

75.6 

91.6 

70.0 

65.2 

May 

94.5 

98.6 

106.7 

98.6 

89.0 

74.1 

59.0 

63.2 

73.6 

86.6 

73.6 

91.1 

69.3 

67.5 

June -- 

96.0 
96.0 

99.7 
101.0 

106.8 
104.7 

99.1 
101.0 

86.6 
85.2 

73.1 
72.7 

58.5 
59.0 

64.7 
68.5 

74.6 
75.0 

85.9 
84.1 

73.2 
77.1 

90.7 
88.7 

67.6 
67.5 

67.4- 

July 

66.3 

August 

95.5 

101.2 

101.1 

101.6 

87.6 

71.9 

59.5 

68.1 

77.4 

83.3 

84.7 

86.8 

66.8 

September.  _ 

94.6 

98.6 

102.8 

102.5 

87.1 

70.8 

60.3 

68.9 

80.1 

83.6 

86.5 

84.3 

66.7 

October 

95.5 

100.4 

104.1 

100.6 

86.6 

68.7 

59.7 

68.3 

81.1 

83.5 

83.7 

81.4 

66.7 

November... 

93.4 

100.2 

103.1 

99.3 

83.1 

66.8 

59.1 

69.0 

82.1 

81.8 

83.5 

77.9 

65.9 

December... 

92.8 

101.0 

101.9 

98.9 

80.9 

64.0 

57.8 

67.8 

83.3 

80.2 

86.1 

76.1 

67.5 

Yearly  aver- 

age  

95.2 

98.2 

104.2 

100.0 

88.7 

72.3 

69.8 

64.1 

75.8 

84.9 

79.5 

86.5 

68.9 

THIRD  QUARTILE 


January 

February 

March 

April -. 

May. 

June.. _ 

July.. 

August :. 

September. . 

October 

November... 
December. . . 
Yearly  aver- 
age  


104.0 

103.5 

99.9 

98.3 

101.3 

86.9 

76.7 

68.9 

77.2 

87.0 

81.5 

85.3 

83.7 

103.6 

103.8 

99.0 

98.8 

101.5 

87.2 

76.3 

68.2 

78.2 

87.3 

81.4 

86.3 

83.8 

103.3 

103.3 

98.6 

96.9 

100.2 

85.3 

76.7 

68.1 

80.0 

87.6 

81.4 

86.7 

83.5 

103.  4 

103.2 

98.6 

97.3 

98.6 

84.5 

76.6 

68.6 

80.7 

86.9 

82.0 

86.9 

83.1 

103.1 

103.3 

99.7 

99.5 

93.5 

82.9 

76.1 

70.5 

80.3 

86.3 

81.0 

87.0 

82.4 

104.0 

102.9 

99:6 

100.5 

93.6 

81.3 

75.2 

72.1 

81.1 

86.2 

81.2 

87.8 

81.4 

104.4 

102.0 

99.4 

102.3 

90.8 

81.1 

73.6 

75.5 

82.7 

85.7 

82.8 

86.8 

80.9 

\0X  5 

101.2 

97.5 

101.5 

90.5 

80.0 

71.5 

78.2 

82.8 

83.0 

85.7 

85.9 

80.2 

103.8 

101.6 

97.7 

101.5 

91.1 

79.4 

69.6 

80.6 

85.4 

83.2 

86.3 

86.4 

79.2 

104.  5 

101.0 

99.7 

101.9 

90.4 

79.3 

69.9 

79.6 

87.1 

82.9 

8.5.3 

86.1 

78.2 

103.8 

101.1 

98.3 

100.9 

88.6 

78.1 

69.5 

77.9 

87.1 

82.8 

85.0 

85.6 

77.4 

103.8 

101.2 

98.3 

100.0 

86.8 

77.8 

69.1 

76.9 

86.7 

82.9 

85.3 

84.4 

77.5 

103.8 

102.3 

98.9 

100.0 

93.9 

82.0 

73.4 

73.7 

82.4 

85.1 

83.3 

86.3 

80.9 

77.8 
77.5 
77.4 
77.5 
77.5 
77.5 
77.0 


FOURTH  QUARTILE 


January 

February 

March 

April 

May 

June 

July 

August 

September. - 

October 

November... 
December. .. 
Yearly  aver- 
age  


103.2 

101.7 

104.0 

102.5 

102.2 

102.7 

101.9 

101.9 

102.7 

ini.  7 

101.9 

103.5 

101.6 

101.7 

104.3 

102.6 

101.7 

104.4 

102.8 

101.1 

103.8 

101.1 

100.6 

101.3 

101.5 

100.2 

100.8 

102.5 

101.5 

100.1 

102.5 

102.8 

100.0 

102.9 

102.8 

99.7 

102.2 

101.6 

102.3 

100.1 
101.8 
101.3 
100.4 
100.1 
100.2 
100.9 
100.7 
100.5 
99.0 
97.7 
97.7 


96.7 

87.0 

76.8 

67.0 

75.6 

85.1 

86.0 

88.0 

84.7 

96.8 

87.0 

76.2 

65.1 

76.7 

87.1 

85.7 

87.0 

84.4 

96.  7 

86.0 

75.4 

65.2 

76.9 

86.8 

84.9 

80.8 

83.3 

96.4 

84.4 

74.2 

67.0 

77.1 

87.5 

83.8 

86.9 

81.8 

95.5 

83.5 

72.3 

69.1 

78.6 

86.4 

82.3 

86.7 

79.6 

93.6 

83.2 

70.8 

70.1 

80.2 

84.9 

81.9 

87.0 

79.5 

93.0 

82.8 

70.6 

73.9 

80.2 

85.4 

83.6 

87.6 

79.2 

93.0 

82.6 

70.7 

74.6 

81.6 

86.3 

85.9 

85.8 

77.8 

31.1 

81.4 

70.0 

75.1 

83.4 

86.8 

85.5 

85.8 

77.3 

■10.9 

80.9 

69.5 

75.6 

83.7 

86.0 

84.6 

85.7 

77.2 

•8.8 

80.5 

69.4 

76.1 

83.8 

86.1 

84.7 

85.0 

76.7 

87.8 

80.1 

69.4 

75.2 

84.2 

86.8 

86.3 

84.7 

77.2 

93.3 

83.3 

72.1 

71.2 

80.0 

86.2 

84.6 

86.4 

79.9 

77.1 
76.8 
77.9 
78.1 
78.0 
78.0 
78.1 


Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


261 


Electric  refrigerators — number  sold,  retail  value,  average  realization  at  retail,  arid 

wholesale  price  index 

(Chart  XII  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  113) 


Year 

Number 
sold  I 

Total  retail 
value ' 

Unit 
retail 
value ' 

Wholesale 
price  index 
(1932=100)' 

1927 --- 

375,  000 
535,  000 
778, 000 
79 i,  000 
906.  000 
798,  000 
1,016,000 
1,  283, 000 

1,  568,  000 
1,996,000 

2.  310. 000 
1,  240, 000 

.$131,260,000 
178, 690. 000 
227,176,000 
217,525,000 
233,  748,  000 
155,610,000 
172.  720. 000 
220,  676, 000 
253. 648,  000 
327,  344.  000 
395,  010.  000 
213,  280,  000 

$350 
334 
292 
275 
258 
195 
170 
172 
162 
164 
171 
172 

1928     - 

1929.  _.. 

1930 - 

1931 __. 

1932 

100  0 

1933                        .              .... 

86  7 

1934          - 

90  9 

1935        

89  2 

1936 - 

80  6 

1937                                     

93  9 

1938               

96  3 

>  Source:  Electrical  Merchandi.'ing. 
2  Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


Electric  washing  machines- 


-number  sold,  retail  value,  average  realization  at  retail, 
and  wholesale  price  index 


(Chart  XIII  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  114) 


Year 

Number 
sold  ' 

Total  retail 
value  1 

Unit 
retail 
value  I 

AVholesale 
prire  index 
(1932=100)  » 

1927 - 

775,  661 

809, 884 

956, 000 

802. 000 

812, 000 

569, 830 

966, 698 

1.121,137 

1,  228,  774 

1,528,585 

1,  405. 405 

1, 032, 956 

$110,925,000 
108,000.000 
107. 900.  000 
83.  809.  000 
69.  020. 000 
33.  619.  970 
59, 935.  276 
72.  873,  905 
79.931,748 
100.947.753 
105.  860. 857 
74, 279, 866 

$143.  01 
133.35 
112.87 
101.  50 
85.  00 
59.00 
62.00 
65.00 
65.  05 
66.04 
72.24 
71.91 

211  0 

1928 

172  8 

1929                 

153  8 

19.30          

138  2 

1931 -.- 

121  1 

1932                 .... 

100  0 

19.33 --. 

82  3 

1934 

80  6 

1935 

80  6 

1936  .       

86  7 

1937 

86.7 

1938. - - , 

86.7 

•  Source:  Electrical  Merchandising. 
>  Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


Vacuum   cleaners — number   sold,   retail   value,   average   realization   at   retail,   and 

wholesale  price  index 


(Chart  XIV  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p 

115) 

Year 

Number 
soldi 

Total  retail 
value  1 

Unit  re- 
tail value' 

Wholesale 
price   index 
(1932=100)» 

1927 

1,194,614 

.   1,219.460 

1, 395,  745 

1,  170, 339 

877,  695 

557,  288 

739, 354 

968, 376 

1, 200, 940 

1,510,9.53 

1,706.337 

1, 297,  530 

$58, 536, 086 
60, 973, 000 
64, 810,  970 
55, 987,  704 
37,310,822 
19, 600, 756 
30, 271, 330 
43,  555, 465 
54, 709,  769 
67,456,541 
77,  783,  784 
63, 986, 896 

$49.00 
50  00 
46.43 
47.84 
42.51 
35.  17 
40.94 
44.98 
45.56 

44.  65 

45.  59 
49.31 

129. 1 

1928 

1929 

129.1 
125. 1 

1030 

121  2 

1931 

112.0 

1932 _ 

100.0 

1933 

95  » 

1934 

102.5 

1935 

93  0 

1936 

86. 1 

1937 

86  t 

1938 

86.1 

'  Source:  Electrical  Merchandising. 
'  Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


262 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Electric  ranges — number  sold,  retail  valtie,  average  realization  at  retail,  and  wholesale 

price  index 

(Chart  XV  based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  1 16) 


Year 

Number 
sold ' 

Total  retail 
value ' 

Unit  re- 
tail value  > 

Wholesale 
price  index 
(1932=100)> 

1927                      

102,000 
135,000 
162,  781 
180,000 
115,000 
60, 000 
50,000 
123,000 
215, 000 
318,000 
405,000 
275,000 

6,  539,  566 
22,175,000 
25,270,000 
27,000,000 
18,795,000 
9,000,000 
7,100,000 
15, 990, 000 
27, 305, 000 
41,413,140 
64,270,000 
39,875,000 

$162. 15 
164.26 
165.40 
150. 00 
163.43 
150. 00 
142. 00 
130.00 
127.00 
130.23 
134. 00 
145.00 

132.4 

1928                  

134.2 

1929           - 

126.9 

1930 

97.0 

1931                     --- 

97.0 

1932                 -- - 

100.0 

1933 --- 

93.6 

1934                       

99.4 

1935 

88.0 

1936         .  --.: 

89.2 

1937      

97.2 

1938                            

98.1 

1  Source:  Electrical  Merchandising. 
*  Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


Sales  and  saturation  * 
(Chart  XVI.based  on  the  following  statistical  data  appears  on  p.  119) 


Electric  refrigerators 

Power  washing 
machines 

Vacuum  cleaners 

Electric  ranges 

Year 

Number 
sold 

Percent 

of  homes 

using 

Number 
sold 

Percent 

of  homes 

using 

Number 
sold 

Percent 

of  homes 

using 

Number 
sold 

Percent 

of  homes 

using 

1927       

375, 000 

535,000 

778, 000 

791,000 

906,000 

798, 000 

1,016,000 

1,283,000 

1,568,000 

1,996,000 

2,310,000 

1,240,000 

4.3 
6.4 
9.4 
12.8 
17.1 
21.6 
24.6 
29.3 
34.2 
41.1 
49.4 
51.7 

775,661 

809,884 

956, 000 

802,000 

812.000 

569, 830 

966, 698 

1, 121, 137 

1,  228, 774 

1, 528,  585 

1,465,405 

1,032,956 

28.4 
30.2 
33.4 
35.1 
40.8 
39.4 
43.9 
46.0 
48.8 
52.5 
55.5 
57.6 

1, 194, 614 

1,  219,  460 

1,395,745 

1,  170,  339 

877,  695 

557,  288 

739,  354  ■ 

968, 376 

1, 200, 940 

1,510,953 

1,  706, 337 

1, 297,  530 

38.8 
40.7 
43.6 
44.4 
45.4 
46.6 
48.5 
48.1 
48.3 
48.9 
48.8 
49.0 

102, 000 
135,000 
152,  781 
180,000 
1 15, 000 
00,000 
50,000 
123,000 
215,000 
318,000 
405, 000 
275,000 

3.3 

1928 

3.8 

1929 

4.4 

1930       .   

4.8 

1931 

6.3 

1932 

5.5 

1933 

5.8 

1934 

6.1 

1936. 

6.8 

1936       .     ... 

7.9 

1937. 

9.0 

1938       ..     .. 

0.6 

1  Percent  of  wired  homes. 
Source:  Electrical  Merchandising. 


) 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


263 


Household  equipment  ownership  by  income  groups,  1936-36 — Percentage  of  families 
reporting  ownership,  selected  cities  by  regions 

(Charts  XVII  to  XX  based  on  tne  following  statistical  data  appear  on  pp.  122-129) 

ELECTRIC  REFRIGERATORS 


New  England 

East  Central 

West 
Central 

South- 
east 

Rocky 
Moun- 
tain 

Pacific 
North- 
west 

Income  class 

1 
S 

.2 
'5 

be 

T3 
0) 

-o'S 

a 

03 

"o 
a 
o 

u 

'S 

bo 

■a 

1 
'3 

a 

to 

'3 

1 
1^ 

Or 
".2 

Hi 

'3 
a 

^'3 
■a 

'3 

•a 

$250  and  under  $500 

12 

9 

9 

21 

27 

30 

43 

42 

56 

61 

69 

86 

82 

100 

10 
12 
20 
28 
36 
43 
56 
59 
71 
81 
81 
90 
89 
85 

8 
12 
12 
27 
36 
42 
51 
60 
63 
66 
75 

'"7" 
15 
27 
35 
48 
54 
56 
57 
67 
73 
78 
89 
82 
88 

10 
4 
11 
22 
37 
46 
56 
63 
66 
76 
72 
88 
90 
99 

"¥ 

16 
28 
43 
55 
57 
66 
61 
70 
65 
72 
78 
68 

6 
11 
25 

33 
40 
64 
64 
01 
71 
66 
87 
84 
78 
84 

ii" 

9 
6 

16 

23 

30 

34 

47 

57 

51 

66 

75 

70 

82 

12 
9 
11 
23 
31 
30 
42 
56 
58 
67 
76 
77 
88 
77 

"is" 

9 
21 
28 
32 
48 
51 
56 
64 
77 
68 
65 
85 

$500  and  under  $750 . 

13 

7 
15 
14 
15 
18 
18 
19 
32 
25 
24 
19 
29 
28 

2 
11 
13 
14 
26 
28 
32 
44 
50 
63 
63 
61 
75 

12 
14 
17 
20 
35 
37 
47 
56 
72 
63 

6 
9 
15 
17 
28 
27 
32 
34 
37 
40 
42 
37 
42 
30 

"e" 

23 
28 
39 
44 
48 
55 
60 
70 
60 
75 
84 
.<2 



$750  and  uader  $1,000 .. 



$1,000  and  under  $1,250 .. 

8 
15 
19 
25 
33 

$1,250  and  under  $1,500    - 

$1,500  and  under  $1,750-.- _ 

$1,750  and  under  $2,000.--     -- 

$2,000  and  under  $2,250- _ 

$2,250  and  under  $2,500.. 

$2,500  and  under  $3,000. 

49 
62 

54 

58 

$3,000  and  under  $3,500. 

$3,W0  and  under  $4,000 

$4,000  and  under  $5,000.. 

$5,000  and  under  $7,500 

71 

$7,500  and  under  $10,000 

$7,500  and  over.    ..    . 

66 

95 

92 

$10,000  and  over..- 

11 

50 

POWER  WASHING  MACHINES 


$250  and  under  $500-   

24 
34 
54 

:8 

04 
63 
65 
51 
59 
63 
64 

19 

62 
72 
77 
79 
81 
83 
82 
75 
75 
68 
78 
67 
80 

56 
63 

77 
74 
88 
84 
84 
80 
77 
86 
78 

66 
55 
70 
70 
73 
76 
68 
70 
71 
76 
81 
74 
82 
85 

46 
44 
66 
69 
73 
70 
75 
70 
73 
66 
67 
56 
66 
60 

27 
55 
45 
56 
62 
57 
68 
65 
67 
51 
48 
68 
68 
79 

31 
45 
64 
61 
61 
69 
67 
70 
70 
76 
69 
75 
79 

63 

$500  and  under  $750 

$750  and  under  $1,000 

13 
3 

7 

6 

2 

4 

5 

9 

14 

8 

13 

11 

10 

14 

6 
7 
10 
14 
19 
18 
21 
22 
37 
34 
32 
32 

18 
25 
42 
43 
46 
45 
45 
53 
43 
54 
56 
51 
59 

22 
25 
40 
46 
44 
54 
55 
48 
52 
56 
52 
53 
48 
41 

57 
59 
68 
77 
76 
81 
80 
82 
77 
83 
79 
84 
82 
86 

5 

9 
12 

9 
12 
17 
10 
16 
12 
17 

6 
22 

2 
5 

4 

10 

6 

9 

6 

10 

11 

14 

7 

7 

13 

25 
31 
45 
51 
48 
48 
51 
52 
52 
57 
43 
61 
53 
39 

53 
66 

$1,000  and  under  $1,250    - 

80 

$1,250  and  under  $1,500 

71 

$1,500  and  under  $1,750 

69 

$1,750  and  under  $2,000. 

80 

$2,000  and  under  $2.250 

73 

$2,250  and  under  $2,500 

$2,500  and  under  $3,000. 

77 
72 

$3,000  and  under  $3,500 

73 

$3,500  and  under  $4,000-.. 

77 

$4,000  and  under  $5,000 

87 

$5,000  and  under  $7.500 .  .. 

83 

$7..500  and  under  $10,000 

$7,500  and  over 

47 

29 

82 

$10,000  and  over 

16 

63 

VACUUM  CLEANERS 


$2.50  and  under  $500 

$500  and  under  $750 

$750  and  under  $1,000  ..- 
$1,000  and  under  $1,250-. 
$1,250  and  under  $1,.500.. 
$1,500  and  under  $1,750.- 
$1,750  and  under  $2,000-- 
$2,000  and  under  $2,250- 
$2,250  and  under  $2,500-. 
$2,,'i00  and  under  $3,000.. 
$3,000  and  under  $3.500.. 
$3,500  and  under  $4,000-. 
$4,000  and  under  .$5.000.. 
$5,000  and  under  $7,.'',00- 
$7,500  and  under  $10,000. 

$7,500  and  over 

$10,000  and  over. -- 


100 


20 

40  30 

25  46 

42  48 


37 
22 
43 
40 
52 
72 
68 
78 
69 
92 
90 
95 
96 


100 


247140 — 11— No.  1 m 


264 


CONCENTRATIOM  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Household  equipment  ownership  by  incoviO  groups,  19S5-36 — Percentage  of  families 
reporting  ownership,  selected  cities  by  regions — Continued 


RADIOS 


Income  class 


New  England 


$250  and  under  $500. _. 

$500  andninder  $750. 

$750  and  under  $1.000 

$1,000  and  under  $1,250 

$1,250  and  under  $1,500 

$1,500  and  under  $1,750 

$1,750  and  under  $2.000 

$2,000  and  under  $2,250 '100 

$2,250  and  under  $2,500 99 

$2,500  and  under  $3,000 ..|  99 

$.3,000  and  und?r  $3,500 98 

$3,500  and  under  $4,000 jlOO 

$4,000  and  under  $5,000... j  99' 

$5,000  and  under  $7,500 97 

$7,500  and  under  $10,000 I  97 

$7,500  and  over '. — 

$10,000  and  over ilOO 


97 

95 

94 

98 

99 

99 
100  I  98 

99  98 
100  100 
100  100 
100    100 


Kast  Central 


74 
91 
88  I  93 
87     96 


97 


West 
Central 


South- 
east 


Rocky 
Moun- 
tain 


Pacific 

North- 
west 


99 


100 
85 
90 
92 
97 


100 
100 
100 
100 


Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics:  Study  of  Consumer  Purchases,  Urban  Series,  1935-36. 

Note. — These  data  are  compiled  from  a  study  of  urban  consumer  purchases  conducted  during  1935-3*^ 
by  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.  The  study  relates  to  nonreiief  families  including  husband  and  wife, 
both  native-born,  in  31  selected  cities  throughout  the  ruuntry.  The  data  include  only  equipment  owned 
at  the  end  of  the  schedule  year,  and  all  hgures  based  upon  number  of  families  in  the  three-way  control 
(occupation,  income,  family  type)  represent  weighted  data. 


I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


265 


Income  residual  after  primary  expenditures  '  by  income  groups,  19S5-S6 — Nonrelief 
white  families,  including  husband  and  wife,  both  native  born  ^ 


(Chart  XXI  based 

on  the  following  statistical  data 

appears  on  p. 

132-3) 

New  England 

East  Central 

West 
Central 

South- 
east 

Rocky 

Moun- 
tain 

Pacific 

North- 
west 

Family  income  class 

"o 
a 
o 

1 

.2 

1-1 

ii 

a 

CO 

"3 
£ 

ta 

.2 
'a 

a 

03 

'5 
1^ 

.2 
'3 

Hi 

S"3 

'3 

ca 
1-5 

T3 

$250  and  under  $500     . 

-69 
-6 
6 
13 
16 
21 
22 
29 
29 
34 
33 
42 
46 
45 

-28 
-11 
10 
14 
22 
20 
27 
29 
30 
33 
41 

-16 
2 
10 
15 
19 
23 
26 
25 
29 
35 
35 
38 
45 
46 
61 

"i 

10 
16 
21 
25 
28 
30 
32 
37 
37 
42 
44 
45 
52 
68 

-28 
-2 
9 
16 
20 
25 
29 
31 
35 
37 
39 
43 
46 
57 

-23 
3 

14 
16 
25 
26 
30 
30 
34 
37 
49 

■(3)- 

12 
14 
19 
23 
26 
30 
34 
35 
36 
41 
42 
43 
55 

-32 
2 
12 
19 
22 
27 
30 
34 
36 
37 
41 
47 
46 
58 

"'"8 
9 
15 
21 
23 
24 
29 
30 
33 
35 
36 
41 
45 
59 

-15 
5 
16 
18 
21 
22 
26 
28 
33 
32 
38 
41 
42 
52 

"-4 
12 
19 
23 
25 
28 
29 
34 
36 
37 
40 
43 
46 
53 

-39 
-6 
5 
15 
19 
28 
24 
32 
33 
31 
37 
41 
42 
57 

"-2 
11 
21 
24 
30 
31 
33 
35 
35 
41 
43 
46 
51 
61 

-''0 

$500  and  unaer  $750  ._.  . 

-43 
-8 
7 
10 
15 
17 
18 
22 
24 
26 
29 
28 
32 
36 
51 

-5 
9 
13 
17 
19 
24 
23 
29 
30 
31 
40 
38 
42 
46 

3 

$750  and  under  $1,000 

?0 

$1,000  and  under  $1,250 

?1 

$1,250  and  under  $1,500 

?8 

$l,.500and  under  $1,750 

$1,750  and  under  $2,000 

$2,000  and  under  $2,250 

$2,250  and  under  $2,500 

$2,500  and  under  $3,000 

29 
30 
32 
36 

39 

$3,000  and  under  $3.500 

3<i 

$3,500  and  under  $4,000 

4? 

$4,000  and  under  $5,000 

$5,i.j0and  under  $7,500 

$7,500  and  under  $10,000 

49 
51 

$10,000  and  over           

'  Figures  show  percent  of  income  remaining  after  expenditures  for  food,  home  maintenance,  clothing  and 
personal  care  are  made. 
'  Family  types  covered  are  as  follows: 

Family  type  I — 2  persons  (husband  and  wife  only). 

Family  type  II— 3  persons  (husband,  wife,  1  child  under  16,  and  no  others). 
Family  type  III — 4  persons  (husband,  wife,  2  children  under  16,  and  no  others). 
Family  type  IV— 3  or  4  persons  (husband,  wife,  1  person  16  or  over,  and  1  or  no  other  person  regard- 
less nf  age) . 

Family  type  V— 5  or  6  persons  (husband,  wife,  1  child  under  16,  1  person  16  or  over,  and  1  or  2  other 
persons  regardless  of  age). 
Family  type  VI— 5  or  6  persons  (husband,  wife,  3  or  4  children  under  16  and  no  others). 
Family  type  VII— 7  or  8  persons  (husband,  wife,  1  child  under  16, 4  or  5  other  persons  regardless  of  age). 
Family  types  VI  and  VII  appear  in  east  central  region  only. 
«  Less  than  1  percent. 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics;  Study  of  Consumer  Purchases,  Urban  Series,  1935-36. 


PART  II 
GEOGRAPHIC  PRICE  STRUCTURES 

BY 

SAUL  NELSON 

ASSISTED  BY 

WILLIAM  C.  FRENCH,  JR. 


PART  II 
PREFACE 

In  part  I  of  this  volume,  it  was  pointed  out  that  the  behavior  and 
structure  of  prices  is  influenced  in  varying  degrees  by  the  policy 
decisions  of  businessmen,  acting  individually  or  in  concert.  Such 
policy  decisions,  within  the  scope  of  their  effectiveness,  must  take 
into  account  not  only  a  nominal  price  quotation  but  also  a  host  of 
collateral  terms  and  conditions  of  sale.  One  of  the  most  important 
of  these  concerns  the  expense  and  responsibility  of  shipping  the  mer- 
chandise from  the  place  of  business  of  the  seller  to  that  of  the  buyer. 
A  quotation  which  implies  that  the  purchaser  must  arrange  and  pay 
for  transportation  is  clearly  different  from  one  which  includes  de- 
livery to  destination. 

It  is  axiomatic  that  there  are  two  points  of  view  in  every  transac- 
tion. The  seller  is  concerned  with  his  net  return  which  excludes 
freight;  the  buyer  with  his  total  outlay  after  freight  has  been  paid. 
In  choosing  between  the  offers  of  two  rival  manufacturers  producing 
identical  commodities,  if  transportation  costs  are  of  any  significance 
in  the  unit  cost  of  a  product,  the  buyer  will  naturally  compare  de- 
livered costs  and  not  net  price  at  the  plant;  the  latter  is  not  his 
immediate  problem.  If  the  merchandise  is  not  identical,  it  is  never- 
theless the  difference  in  delivered  costs  which  he  must  weigh  against 
any  inequalities  of  product. 

This  situation  is  inevitably  reflected  in  commodity  price  structures. 
Sellers,  acting  within  the  field  in  which  they  can  formulate  and  main- 
tain policy,  have  adopted  a  wide  variety  of  practices  with  regard  to 
the  burden  of  shipping  costs.  Differences  in  practice  reflect  partly 
dilferencos  in  market  coiiditions,  partly  administrative  decisions  as  to 
expediency,  and  partly  the  abiliij'^  to  enforce  such  decisions  in  a 
given  economic  and  legal  environment.  Some  sellers  maintain  a 
uniform  price  at  their  plants  to  all  buyers  regardless  of  their  location, 
others  quote  uniform  delivered  prices  in  all  markets  or  within  de- 
fined geographic  zones,  still  others  vary  their  prices  systematicnlly  or 
unsystematieally  in  order  to  meet  c'  undersell  their  nvids  in  all 
markets  in  which  they  wish  to  do  busmess. 

Some  of  these  practices,  notably  basing  point  S3"stems  and  zone 
systems,  result  in  greatly  limiting  or  eliminating  price  competition 
in  the  markets  for  the  commodities  affected,  although  competition 
may  take  other  forms. 

These  types  of  geographic  price  structure,  particularly  the  basing 
point  system,  have  consequently  been  the  subject  of  much  contro- 
vers}^  in  discussions  of  the  problems  of  monopoly  and  eoiupetition  in 
ii,  lustrial  markets.  The  Federal  Trade  Commission  has  conducted 
intensive  studies  of  geographic  price  structures  in  many  industries. 
In  recent  hearings  before  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Com- 

269 


270  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

mittee  the  practices  of  the  steel  industry  with  regard  to  freight  were 
considered  in  great  detail.^ 

There  has  not,  however,  been  any  general  survey  of  the  extent  to 
which  diflPerent  types  of  geographic  price  structure  are  actually 
encountered  in  the  American  economy,  nor  of  the  considerations 
which  favor  the  development  of  one  or  another  type  of  practice. 
Such  information  seems  needed  for  an  adequate  appraisal  of  the 
relationship  between  such  practices  as  basing  point  systems,  zone 
systems,  and  other  means  of  freight  equalization  and  the  pattern  of 
competition  within  an  industry.  Among  the  problems  with  which 
the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  is  immediately  con- 
fronted is  the  adequacy  of  existing  antitrust  legislation  to  cope  with 
geographic  practices  which  may  seem  to  impair  the  efficacy  of  price 
competition. 

Part  II  of  this  volume  is  designed  to  yield  the  factual  basis  needed 
for  such  an  appraisal,  and  as  a  guide  to  policy.  It  does  not  present 
conclusions  nor  recommendations,  which  are  the  province  of  the 
committee.  It  describes  the  geographic  pricing  structures  of  a  wide 
variety  of  commodities;  industrial,  agricultural,  and  extractive.  The- 
list  is  by  no  means  complete,  but  it  is  reasonably  representative. 
The  two  chapters  consider  in  order: 

I.  Types  of  Geographic  Price  Structure:  A  discussion  of  the 
importance  of  the  element  of  freight  as  a  market  factor  and  a  de- 
scription of  the  more  common  types  of  geographic  price  structure. 

II.  Geographic  Practices  in  American  Markets:  A  product  by 
product  analysis  of  the  types  of  geographic  price  structure  currently 
observed  followed  by  -a  summary  indicating  the  extent  of  the  more 
common  types  of  geographic  practice. 

Part  II  was  prepared  by  Saul  Nelson  with  the  assistance  of  William 
C.  French,  Jr.  The  data  relating  to  geographic  price  structures  of 
building  materials  were  assembled  by  Walter  G.  Keim.  Jesse  M. 
Cutts  of  the  Wholesale  Price  Division  provided  much  of  the  basic 
information.  Valuable  assistance  was  accorded  by  trade  association 
officials  and  business  executives  regarding  the  price  structures  of  their 
respective  industries.  Mr.  Edwin  B.  George  of  Dun  &  Brads treet, 
rendered  material  help  in  the  planning  of  this  study. 

'  See  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  Hearings,  Parts  26  and  27. 


CHAPTER  I 
TYPES  OF  GEOGRAPHIC  PRICE  STRUCTURE 

INTRODUCTION 

The  importance  of  transportation  costs. — The  expense  of  physical 
transportation  constitutes  an  important  element  in  the  total  cost  of 
preparing  goods  for  the  market.  According  to  a  recent  estimate  ^  the 
total  cost  of  producing  and  distributing  commodities  for  the  national 
market  during  1929  was  $65,600,000,000.  Thirteen  percent  or 
$8,800,000,000  of  this  total  represented  the  cost  of  transportation. 

According  to  the  same  estimate,  only  $27,100,000,000  of  the 
$65,600,000,000  total  represented  the  cost  of  physical  production 
while  $38,500,000,000  constituted  the  cost  of  distribution.  Conse- 
quently the  cost  of  transporting  commodities  was  almost  one-third  as 
great  as  the  cost  of  physically  producing  them,  and  constituted  23 
percent  of  the  aggregate  bill  for  distribution. 

The  $8,800,000,000  bill  for  transportation  included  a  variety  of  items: 
Rail  freight,  water  freight,  railway  express,  electric  freight,  motor 
trucking,  pipe-line  transportation,  and  parcel  post.  For  most  of  these 
means  of  transportation,  shipping  rates  are  either  fixed  by  law  or  are 
otherwise  out  of  the  control  of  the  shipper  or  receiver  of  the  goods 
transported.  Partly  as  a  result  of  this  situation,  freight  rates  are 
notoriously  rigid;  their  variations  are  narrow  and  bear  no  apparent 
relationship  to  the  movement  of  commodity  prices.  Consequently, 
the  bill  for  transportation  becomes  oroportionately  much  more  im- 
portant durmg  periods  when  commodity  prices  are  low  or  falling;  it 
decreases  in  relative  importance  when  commodity  prices  are  high  or 
rising. 

The  data  quoted  for  1929,  therefore,  probably  represent  an  under- 
estimate of  the  significance  of  freight  during  periods  of  low  prices  and 
limited  use  of  resources,  such  as  the  last  decade. 

Unfortunately,  there  are  no  data  readily  available  which  would  indi- 
cate the  size  of  the  total  freight  bill  during  the  period  since  1929. 
Some  information  is  available  relating  to  one  of  the  most  important 
single  components  of  that  bill — rail  freight.  According  to  the  Inter- 
state Commerce  Commission,^  rail  freight  revenue  on  class  I  roads  for 
1930  was  $4,200,000,000,  or  6.7  percent  of  the  total  value  of  commod- 
ities transported.  For  1933,  the  effect  of  the  generally  low  price  leveL 
was  reflected  in  an  increase  of  this  ratio  to  10.7  percent.  As  prices 
rose  again  the  ratio  declined  to  8.5  percent  for  1936,  the  last  date  for 
which  these  data  were  compiled.^ 

'  Does  Distribution  Cost  Too  Much,  Twentieth  Century  Fund,  p.  118. 

'  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  Bureau  of  Statistics,  Freight  Revenue  and  Value  of  Commodities 
Transported  on  Class  I  Steam  Railways  in  the  United  States,  calendar  year  1936. 

'  These  data  are  presented  merely  to  show  trend  and  are  not  at  all  comparable  to  those  in  the  Twentieth 
Century  Fund  publication  previously  cited.  A  major  difference  is  that  the  Interstate  Commerce  Com- 
mission figures  include  numerous  duplications  entering  into  the  est;  nate  of  total  value:  for  example,  iron 
ore  will  first  be  included  as  such  and  will  again  enter  into  the  value  of  shipments  for  semifinished  and  finished 
steel  products.  This  results  in  an  underestimate  of  the  over-all  significance  of  freight  and  thus  differs  from 
the  Twentieth  Century  Fund  data  which  are  based  upon  the  value  of  products  in  final  form. 

271 


272  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Factors  affecting  freight  costs. — The  importance  of  transportation 
costs  varies  very  widely  for  different  kinds  of  products.  Many  factors 
enter  into  the  picture.  One  of  the  most  important  is  the  reLation 
between  the  price  of  the  product  and  its  weight;  other  things  being 
equal,  freight  will  be  relatively  more  significant  for  cheap,  bulky  items 
than  for  those  which  cost  more  per  pound.  For  example,  rail  freight 
revenue  represents  56  percent  of  the  value  of  bituminous  coal  at  des- 
tination and  46  percent  of  the  value  of  salt,  whereas  it  constitutes  less 
than  10  percent  for  sulfur  and  only  5  percent  for  copper  ore. 

For  the  same  reason  freight  will  be  a  less  important  factor  for  man- 
ufactured goods  than  for  their  constituent  raw  materials;  thus  the 
percentage  of  freight  revenue  to  value  at  destination  for  cereal  food 
preparations  is  3.4  percent  as  against  5.9  percent  for  wheat  flour,  S 
percent  for  wheat,  9.3  percent  for  corn,  and  12.4  percent  for  oats. 

Another  significant  factor  is  the  location  of  supply  in  relation  to 
the  market.  Where  production  is  concentrated  within  a  circum- 
scribed area,  while  consumption  is  distributed  throughout  the  United 
States,  the  average  haul  is  likely  to  be  long  and  the  relative  import- 
ance of  freight  considerable.  Wliere  centers  of  production  are  scat- 
tered or  are  located  near  most  important  centers  of  consumption, 
hauls  are  likely  to  be  shorter  and  freight  relatively  less  important. 
More  generally,  if  production  must  be  located  near  sources  of  raw 
material,  freight  for  the  finished  product  will  be  more  important  than 
when  plants  can  be  established  at  or  near  the  markets. 

Reference  may  also  be  made  to  perishability  and  the  consequent 
need  for  special  or  expeditious  handling  which  is  probably  responsible 
for  the  fact  that  freight  constitutes  60  percent  of  value  at  destination 
of  such  products  as  grapes.*  Another  element  may  be  public  policy, 
as  in  the  case  of  the  extremely  low  postal  rates  for  newspapers  and 
periodicals. 

Economic  significance. — Obviously,  these  costs  of  transportation 
must  somehow  be  included  in  the  price  of  the  delivered  product. 
There  are  many  ways  in  which  this  can  be  done.  Ench  buyer  may 
be  required  to  bear  the  full  expense  of  shipping  his  particular  pur- 
chase directly,  or  the  seller  may  choose  to  defray  this  expense  in  the 
first  instance  and  then  to  distribute  it  in  varioiis  ways  among  all  his 
custon^ers.  In  the  sale  of  most  commodities,  practices  witb  regard 
to  the  manner  in  which  freight  charges  are  borne  and  distributed 
among  the  different  buyers  and  sellers  in  the  market  have  developed 
ce:  tain  conventionalized  patterns.  These  practices  are  commonly 
referred  to  as  the  "geographic  price  structure"  for  the  product  in 
question.  The  form  they  take  in  any  particular  case  reflects  the  im- 
pact of  many  forces,  such  as  the  inherent  characteristics  of  the  mar- 
ket, the  requirements  of  law  as  interpreted  by  courts  and  adminis- 
trative agencies,  and  the  policy  decisions  of  businessmen  acting  in 
this  environment.  Geographic  price  structures  in  turn  have  far- 
reaching  economic  effects;  they  influence  the  character  of  competi- 
tion within  an  industry,  the  location  of  its  plants,  and  the  prospects 
of  profit  or  survival  of  individual  concerns. 

However,  the  appraisal  of  the  economic  implications  of  the  dif- 
ferent types  of  geographic  price  structure  encountered  in  American 
industry  is  beyond  the  scope  of  the  present  study.     The  issi.es  raised 

*  In  1933,  when  prices  were  lower,  the  ratio  for  grapes  was  almost  65  percent.     Interstate  Commerce 
Commission,  op.  cit. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  273 

in  such  an  appraisal  are  many  and  complex.  Practices  in  particular 
industries,  such  as  the  basing  point  systems  in  the  steel  and  cement 
industries/  have  been  the  subject  of  considerable  and  intensive 
analysis;  yet  conclusions  regarding  its  merits  and  implications  re- 
main in  considerable  dispute.  It  is  intended  here  merely  to  present 
factual  data  regarding  the  types  of  geographical  price  structure  which 
characterize  different  sectors  of  American  industry  and  thus  to  fur- 
nish a  basis  for  broader  analysis  of  the  problem,  as  well  as  to  permit 
a  better  understanding  of  the  meaning  of  price  and  price  quotations 
in  different  industries  and  markets. 

Types  of  structure  summarized. — The  cost  of  shipment  enters  directly 
or  indirectly  into  virtually  every  transfer  of  commodities  between 
buyer  aud  seller.  There  is,  however,  a  very  wide  variation  between 
different  industries  and  even  within  industries  as  to  the  manner  in 
which  this  element  is  related  to  the  price  quotation  and  charged  to 
differently  located  buyers.  Although  there  is  usually  a  degree  of 
uniformity  in  geographic  pricing  practice  between  companies  which 
are  competing  in  the  sale  of  identical  or  similar  products,  this  is  not 
necessarily  the  case.  Moreover,  the  same  company  may  vary  its 
methods  of  price  quotation  for  different  parts  of  the  country  or  to 
meet  special  situations  encountered  in  particular  transactions  or 
groups  of  transactions.  Changes  in  structure  are  also  likely  to  occur 
from  time  to  time  under  the  impact  of  altering  market  conditions  or 
the  requirements  imposed  by  Government  through  law  or  admmis- 
trative  action.  Consequently,  any  analysis  of  geographic  price 
structures  must  start  with  a  recognition  that  they  are  not  rigid  or 
immutable,  although  specific  patterns  may  persist  for  long  periods  of 
time  in  individual  industries.  Before  proceeding  to  consider  different 
types  of  geographic  structure  i,n  detail,  it  is  useful  to  summarize 
briefly  patterns  of  variation  which  may  actuall}^  occur.  Among  the 
more  common  are — 

(1)  The  amount  paid  by-  each  buyer  varies  in  precise  accordance 
with  the  cost  of  transporting  the  product  from  point  of  shipment  to 
point  of  destination. 

(2)  Unsystematic  schemes  of  freight  equalization  in  which  a  seller 
will  reduce  his  price  on  particular  transactions  in  order  to  meet  or 
belter  the  offer  of  a  competing  seller  who  is  more  advantageously 
located. 

(3)  Systematip  schemes  of  freight  equalization  in  which  this  type  of 
adjustment  follows  some  set  pattern  which  is  generally  observed  by 
all  or  most  competing  sellers. 

(4)  Single  or  multiple  basing-point  schemes  in  which  the  amount  of 
freight  charged  to  individual  buyers  varies  in  accordance  with,  shipping 
costs  from  one  or  more  basing  points  recognized  by  the  mdustry. 
These  basing  points  usually  represent  important  producing  centers, 
but  in  a  true  basing-point  system  there  will  always  be  some  plants 
which  are  not  located  at  any  basing  point. 

(5)  Zone  pricing  in  which  the  delivered  prices  paid  by  buyers  are 
uniform  throughout  certain  conventionally  accepted  geographic  areas 
but  vary  between  areas. 

•  Probaoiy  the  most  intensive  work  on  this  subject  has  been  done  by  the  Federal  Trade  CommissioDi 
See  for  example  Price  Bases  Inquiry,  The  Basing  Point  Formula  and  Cement  Prices,  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission  March  1932. 


274  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(6)  Uniform  delivered  prices  in  which  the  same  dehvered  price  is 
paid  by  all  buyers  in  the  United  States  wherever  located. 

(7)  Unsystematic  price  variation  in  which  the  prices  in  particular 
markets  show  no  direct  relation  to  shipping  costs.  They  may  be  set 
arbitrarily  to  meet  peculiar  competitive  conditions,  or  they  may  vary 
constantly  with  day-to-day  changes  in  supply  or  demand  in  those 
markets. 

(8)  Various  combinations  of  the  above. 

The  differences  enumerated  all  relate  to  the  way  in  which  the 
amounts  paid  by  buyers  and  the  net  returns  of  sellers  vary  on  sales 
to  different  localities.  In  addition,  the  form  of  quotation  may  have  a 
bearing  upon  the  implications  of  the  sales  contract,  particularly  as 
regards  the  distribution  of  risk  of  shipment  between  buyer  and  seller. 
Thus  there  is  a  distinction  in  principle  between  prices  which  are 
quoted  at  the  point  of  shipment — f.  o.  b.**  pricing — and  prices  which 
are  quoted  at  the  point  of  delivery — delivered  pricing.^  In  the  former 
case,  transfer  of  title  to  goods  may  take  place  at  the  point  of  ship- 
ment, such  as  the  seller's  plant  or  warehouse,  and  the  cost  and  respon- 
sibility of  shipment  is  borne  by  the  buyer.  In  the  latter  case,  transfer 
of  title  may  not  occur  until  the  merchandise  is  delivered  to  the  point 
at  which  the  seller  is  located,  with  the  risk  of  shipment  borne  directly 
by  the  seller.  However,  the  point  at  which  title  passes  and  burden  of 
risk  in  any  specific  instance  cannot  be  determined  merely  by  referring 
to  the  form  of  the  quotation,  since  other  factors  such  as  the  terms  of 
the  bill  of  lading,  the  sales  contract  and  the  intent  of  the  parties  are 
also  involved. 

Insofar  as  this  distinction  relates  merely  to  the  form  of  quotation, 
it  does  not  carry  with  it  any  necessary  implication  as  to  the  variation 
of  prices  between  differently  located  buyers.  It  is  true  that  basing- 
point  systems,  by  their  very  nature,  require  that  prices  be  quoted  on 
a  delivered  basis.  However,  f.  o.  b.  prices  may  be  so  adjusted  for 
differences  in  freight,  that  the  actual  delivered  cost  of  the  product  is 
the  same  to  all  buyers  throughout  the  United  States  or  within  a  given 
zone;  conversely,  dt  /ered  prices  may  include  the  full  cost  of  freight 
in  every  instance  and  vary  in  precise  accordance  with  differences  in 
shipping  costs.  While  the  latter  situation  is  unusual,  the  former  is 
quite  common.  Many  concerns  quote  prices  f.  o.  b.  plant  with  full 
freight  allowed,  which  is  equivalent  to  a  uniform  delivered  price. 
When  freight  is  thus  "allowed,"  the  buj'^er  ordinarily  pays  the  trans- 
portation agency  in  the  first  instance  and  then  deducts  the  amount 
of  this  payment  from  the  invoice.  In  some  cases,  freight  is  not  onl}^ 
allowed  but  also  prepaid,  under  which  circumstances  the  seller  paj^s 
the  cost  of  shipment  at  the  source,  thus  relieving  the  buyer  of  the 
necessity  for  advancing  freight  charges.^ 

6  These  initials  are  an  abbreviation  for  "free  oil  board"  and  Indicate  that  the  quotation  includes  the 
expense  of  placing  the  merchandise  on  railroad  cars  or  other  means  of  transportation  indicated  at  the  point 
named,  with  the  buyer  bearing  the  expense  and  responsibility  of  shipment  from  that  point  E  g  f  o  b 
cars,  Chicago,  means  that  the  price  includes  placing  the  merchandise  on  ralkoad  cars  at  Chicago 

'In  this  and  the  subsequent  discussion  the  terms  "price"  and  "market"  are  used  both  in  relation  to  the 
point  of  origin  and  the  point  of  destination;  the  specific  meaning  in  each  case  is  indicated  by  the  context 
It  should  be  noted,  however,  that  "price"  and  "market"  to  the  consumer  may  mean  one  thing-  they  may 
mean  quite  another  to  the  businessman;  they  may  have  still  another  meaning  to  government  agencies 
charged  with  the  duty  of  determining  whether  industrial  pricing  policies  suppress  free  and  fair  competition 
It  IS  not  the  purpose  of  this  monograph  to  take  any  position  w;„h  respect  to  these  various  viewpoints  about 
price"  and  "market"  or  their  legal  and  economic  implications. 

«  The  distinction  between  "freight  allowed"  and  "freight  prepaid,"  since  it  is  reflected  in  the  gross  amount 
of  the  invoice,  may  also  aflect  the  amount  of  cash  and  other  discounts  which  may  be  figured  on  the  gross 
amount  as  a  base. 

Page  274.    Mono.  1. 
247149—40 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER  275 

However,  too  much  emphasis  should  not  be  imputed  to  the  mere 
form  of  quotation,  even  as  it  relates  to  the  point  at  which  title  passes. 
Thus  it  may  be  questioned  whether  the  free  and  unreserved  transfer 
of  title  at  the  point  of  shipment  is  compatible  with  any  system  involv- 
ing freight  allowances.  Certainly  it  is  not  ordinarily  within  the  intent 
of  the  seller  that  the  buyer  should  be  free  to  divert  the  shipment  before 
it  reaches  its  announced  destination.  If  this  were  not  true,  it  would 
be  possible  for  a  buyer  located  at  some  distance  from  the  point  of  ship- 
ment to  take  advantage  of  his  freight  allowance  by  reselling  the  mer- 
chandise at  a  profit  to  another  buyer  who  is  located  closer  to  the  source 
of  supply  and  who  would  not,  therefore,  be  entitled  to  as  large  an 
allowance.  Presumably,  therefore,  the  reservation  that  the  shipment 
must  proceed  to  its  announced  destination  is  implied  in  any  system 
involving  freight  allo'vances.  To  that  extent  any  such  system  diffei's 
from  straight  f.  o.  b.  mill  pricing  in  which  the  buyer  can  do  as  he  will 
with  the  merchandise  once  he  receives  delivery  at  the  mill  door. 

In  addition,  reference  may  be  made  to  the  type  of  quotation  known 
as  "c.  i.  f."  which  is  often  used  in  connection  with  goods  shipped  by 
water.  The  initials  represent  an  abbreviation  for  "cost,  insurance, 
freight,"  and  mean  that  the  quoted  price  includes  the  cost  of  freight 
and  insurance  to  the  port  specified,  and  delivery  in  good  condition  to 
railroad  cars  or  trucks  at  that  port,  with  the  buyer  bearing  the  expense 
and  responsibility  of  further  transportation.^  The  initials  "f.  a.  s.", 
meaning  "free  alongside,"  are  also  used  in  connection  with  water  trans- 
portation and  differ  from  "c.  i.  f."  in  that  the  buyer  accepts  delivery 
at  the  wharf  and  must  arrange  for  loading  the  merchandise  on  cars  or 
trucks  for  the  land  shipment. 

COMMON   FORMS   OF  STRUCTURE — DEVELOPMENT  AND   CHARACTERISTICS 

The  form  of  geographic  price  structure  which  prevails  in  the  market 
for  any  commodity  reflects  the  operation  of  a  host  of  factors.  Among 
the  more  important  of  these  is  the  intensity  and  focus  of  competition 
including  the  relative  emphasis  upon  price  or  nonprice  rivalry,  the 
degree  of  geographic  concentration  of  the  industry,  the  location  of 
sources  of  supply  in  relation  to  markets,  the  relative  importance  of 
transportation  costs  as  an  element  in  the  price  of  the  commodity,  the 
channels  of  distribution  utilized,  the  extent  of  economic  concentration 
among  sellers  and  among  buyers,  the  interest  of  sellers  in  maintaining 
control  over  resale  prices  and  conditions,  etc.  The  way  in  which 
conditions  of  this  kind  are  actually  reflected  in  the  geographic  price 
structure,  and  the  consistency  with  which  such  a  structure  is  observed, 
will  also  be  affected  very  considerably  by  the  degree  of  freedom  which 
individual  sellers  or  groups  of  sellers  have  in  formulating  and  main- 
taining price  policies.  The  possible  impact  of  these  forces  upon  some 
of  the  more  common  types  of  geographic  price  structure  will  illustrate 
the  issues  involved. 

F.  0.  b.  plant  prices. — Probably  the  simplest  type  of  structure  is  the 
f.  o.  b.  system  of  pricing  with  no  freight  allowed.  Under  this  system 
all  delivery  charges  are  borne  by  the  buyer  who  accepts  delivery  at 
the  point  of  shipment;  the  price  charged  by  the  seller  to  buyers  wiU  not 
be  adjusted  in  any  way  to  reflect  the  varying  transportation  charges 

»  Less  common  variants  of  this  type  of  quotation  arc  "c.  i.  f.  e.",  which  indicate  that  the  quotation  ia- 
eludes  provision  for  converting  foreign  exchange;  and  "c.  &  f."  which  mean  that  the  buyer  must  arrauge 
for  insurance  during  the  marine  transit. 


276  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

which  the  latter  are  called  upon  to  pay  because  of  their  different  loca- 
tions. The  same  practical  result,  except  as  relates  to  risk  of  ship- 
ment, can  be  achieved  by  a  delivered  price  system  in  which  the 
delivered  price  includes  actual  full  freight  in  every  case,  but  this  is  not 
a  usual  practice.  This  type  of  structure  yields  the  seller  a  net  return 
on  all  sales  which  is  independent  of  his  destination  and  which  will 
be  uniform  insofar  as  all  other  terms  of  sale  (e.  g.,  quantity  discounts) 
are  identical.  It  is  most  likely  to  be  encountered  in  those  cases  in 
which  there  is  no  severe  pressure  upon  the  seller  to  reduce  his  prices 
in  certain  markets  to  meet  the  competition  of  some  rival  who  happens 
to  be  more  advantageously  located  with  respect  to  that  market, 
'^his  condition  will  be  fulfilled,  for  example,  when  all  sellers  of  a  given 
commodity  are  located  in  a  narrowly  circumscribed  geographic  area 
so  that  the  cost  of  shipping  the  product  from  any  plant  to  any  market 
is  practically  the  same  as  that  of  shipping  it  from  any  other  plant  to 
the  same  market.  Turpentine,  which  is  produced  largely  in  Florida 
and  Georgia  is  an  example,  as  is  the  women's  dress  industry  ^°  which 
is  almost  entirely  concentrated  in  the  New  York  area,  and  the  automo- 
bile industry  in  Michigan  before  the  establishment  of  assembling 
plants  at  other  points.  These  conditions  could  also  be  fulfilled  by  a 
seller  who  enjoys  an  outright  monopoly,  or  who  has  succeeded  in 
creating  unique  consumer  acceptance  for  his  product,  so  that  there  is 
no  effective  pressure  from  substitute  products  at  anj^  point.  A  similar 
situation  may  occur  where  freight  is  so  small  a  part  of  the  price  of  the 
finished  product  that  it  does  not  constitute  an  important  competitive 
factor,  particularly  wdiere  emphasis  is  upon  nonprice  elements  such  as 
style;  thus  most  apparel  is  sold  on  the  basis  of  a  uniform  f.  o.  b.  price. 
The  existence  of  material  differences  in  the  quality  or  design  of  com- 
peting products  may  even  permit  uniform  f.  o.  b.  plant  prices  to  be 
used  in  connection  with  items  for  which  freight  is  a  material  element; 
thus  milling  and  grinding  machines  may  be  sold  on  this  basis. 

These  considerations  relate,  of  course,  only  to  the  territory  actual!}^ 
served  by  the  seller  in  question.  The  existence  of  numerous  sources 
of  supply  throughout  the  United  States — or  outside  it — neo(^  not 
affect  the  structure  so  long  as  the  product  irom  each  source  is  dis- 
tributed in  a  geographically  circamscribed  area  which  does  not 
seriously  ov^erlap  the  area  served  by  other  sources.  For  example, 
the  existence  of  important  phosphate  rock  mines  in  Tennessee  does 
not  appreciably  affect  the  pricing  practices  of  the  producers  of  phos- 
phate pebble  in  Florida,  so  long  as  they  sell  in  distinct  markets. 

Freight  equalization. — When  there  is  more  than  one  geographic 
source  of  supply  and  one  seller  seeks  to  expand  his  territory  into  an 
area  contiguous  to  the  other,  modification  of  this  simple  structure  is 
likely  to  occur.  From  the  point  of  view  of  the  buyer,  it  must  be 
emphasized,  the  significant  element  is  the  total  price  which  ue  is  called 
upon  to  pay  at  destination,  and  not  the  seller's  net  realization.  This 
does  not  deny  that  buyers  have  a  very  substantial  interest  in  the 
geographic  pricing  practices  of  sellers  as  they  affect  the  character  or 
intensity  of  competition  and  the  level  or  behavior  of  prices;  the  advan- 
tages derived  from  freight  concessions  or  allowances  are  often  apparent 
rather  than  real.  To  the  individual  buyer  on  any  single  purchase, 
however,  the  total  cost  at  destination  is  the  item  of  immediate  concern. 

'0  This  refers  to  the  woinen's  dress  industry  proper,  and  not  to  the  house  dress  or  wash  frock  industry 
which  is  much  more  decentralized. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  277 

In  the  sale  of  a  standard  commodity,  therefore,  sellers  who  distrib- 
ute through  a  wide  geographic  area  are  likeh^  to  meet  constant  pres- 
sure to  adjust  tliei'  prices  on  individual  transactions  to  meet  the 
offer  of  competing  sellers  who  happen  to  be  nearer  freightwise.  To 
illustrate:  assume  two  rival  producers  located  in  New  York  and 
Chicago,  respectivel}",  who  are  selling  identical  commodities.  Suppose 
that  Philadelphia  and  St.  Louis  are  two  important  markets,  that  both 
sellers  are  using  a  simple  f.  o.  b.  system  of  pricing,  and  that  the  plant 
prices  of  both  are  initially  identical.  Obviously,  the  New  York  pro- 
ducer will  not  be  able  to  sell  in  St.  Louis,  nor  the  Chicago  producer  in 
Philadelphia.  Originally  this  m.ay  have  presented  no  problem,  be- 
cause the  New  York  manufacturer  found  ample  markets  in  eastern 
territory,  while  the  Chicago  producer  was  able  to  dispose  of  all  his 
merchandise  in  the  \lidwest.  With  the  passing  of  time,  however, 
and  the  expansion  of  plant  facilities,  one  proflucer  may  readily  find 
himself  with  surplus  capacity  or  surplus  product  on  his  hands  which 
cannot  at  the  moment  be  absorbed  by  the  territory  which  he  has  been 
accustomed  to  serve.  If  under  such  circumstances  the  New  York 
firm  learns  that  a  buyer  in  St.  Louis  is  in  the  market  for  a  substantial 
order,  it  is  likely  to  attempt  to  invade  the  St.  Louis  territory  and  to 
meet  or  better  the  offer  of  the  Chicago  producer  at  that  point. 

Of  course,  one  way  in  which  the  New  York  producer  can  reduce  his 
price  to  the  St.  Louis  buyer  sufficiently  to  meet  Chicago  competition 
would  be  simply  to  cut  his  plant  price  to  all  comers  by  an  amount 
sufficient  to  compensate  for  the  difference  in  freight.  In  general, 
however,  such  a  course  would  involve  so  large  a  loss  on  sales  in  nearby 
areas  that  the  benefit  from  making  occasional  sales  in  remoter  areas 
would  be  completely  lost.  Consequently  a  much  more  expedient  and 
likely  decision  would  be  to  cut  prices  only  on  the  St.  Louis  transaction 
by  an  amount  approximately  equal  to  the  difference  in  freight.  If 
prices  are  quoted  on  a  delivered  basis,  this  can  be  done  directly;  if 
an  f.  o.  b.  system  is  used,  the  quotation  can  be  reduced  by  the  discount 
necessary  to  make  the  sale. 

Some  such  process  of  "freight  absorption"  is  likel}^  to  occur  when- 
ever geographically  separated  sellers  of  reasonably  similar  products  are 
•competing  in  the  same  markets  and  is  probably  the  alternative  to  a 
strict  limitation  of  the  sales  territory  of  each  seller  to  the  area  which 
he  can  serve  most  economically.  The  tendency  to  sell  in  remote 
areas  is  augmented  by  fluctuations  in  local  demand,  which  are  con- 
stantly and  inevitably  occurring,  and  as  soon  as  sales  tei-ritories  over- 
lap some  form  of  freight  absorption  or  "equalization"  is  likely  to  occur.'* 

It  should  be  emphasized  that  the  foregoing  illustration  is  strictly 
hypothetical.  It  was  presented  merely  to  suggest  the  way  in  which 
pressure  to  adjust  delivered  prices  in  competitive  territories  may  arise 
initially.  The  actual  process  of  adjustm.ent  is  rarely  so  simple  or 
^'natural."  In  practice,  freight  equalization  assumes  much  more  con- 
ventional forms  than  the  sort  of  sim.ple  adjustment  to  m.eet  the  needs 
of  the  individual  transaction  which  has  just  been  described.  In 
many  industries  there  are  systematic  schemes  of  freight  equalization 
which  are  more  or  less  closely  observed  by  all  sellers  and  which  are 
far  too  elaborate  in  detail  to  represent  purely  spontaneous  develop- 

"  Something  akin  to  equalization  may  occur  within  the  organization  of  a  large  company,  as  well  as  between 
competitors.  Thus  a  large  agricultural  implement  producer  has  a  main  factory  in  Chicago  with  numerous 
more  specialized  plants  in  other  cities.  On  sales  from  these  latter  plants  freight  is  charged  from  plant  or 
from  Chicago,  whichever  is  lower. 


278  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

ments.  Moreover  these  schemes  are  often  found  in  conjunction  with 
arrangements  for  maintaining  well-defined  relationships  between  the 
prices  at  different  plants,  thereby  permitting  a  substantial  degree  of 
control  over  the  entire  price  structure.  Such  practices,  if  rigidly  ob- 
served, effectively  limit  the  possibility  of  price  competition. 

On  the  other  hand,  it  should  not  be  inferred  that  the  existence  of 
such  a  systematic  scheme  of  freight  equalization  is  per  se  an  indication 
of  the  absence  of  effective  price  competition.*^  All  that  can  be  said 
is  that  the  more  complex  and  conventional  types  of  geographic  price 
structure  often  spring  not  from  natural  adjustments  to  the  market 
but  from  a  conscious  effort  on  the  part  of  concerns  in  an  industry  to 
limit  or  eliminate  price  competition  and  that  they  may  even  be  indis- 
pensable tools  to  this  end.  Thus  although  the  more  obviously  artifi- 
cial types  of  geographic  price  structure  are  frequently  encountered 
under  circumstances  which  give  rise  to  suspicion  of  collusive  restraint 
of  trade,  yet  it  is  not  necessarily  true  that  their  existence  is  either  the 
direct  cause  or  manifestation  of  such  collusion.  It  is  theoretically 
possible,  for  example,  that  aggressive  price  cutting  should  take  place 
within  the  framework  of  such  a  system  as  well  as  without  it. 

Geographic  price  structures  of  this  kind  take  many  forms.  In  the 
case  of  many  heavy  chemicals  such  as  sulfuric  acid,  for  example,  plant 
price  quotations  are  apparently  uniform  for  all  plants  of  all  companies 
throughout  the  United  States.**  Freight  is  equalized  on  the  basis  of 
shipping  costs  from  the  plant  nearest  the  point  of  delivery.**  Since 
the  location  of  all  plants  in  these  industries  is  known,  all  producers 
will  tend  to  quote  the  same  delivered  price  in  any  market. 

Another  common  type  of  equalization  involves  a  division  of  the 
country  into  zones.  Plant  prices  in  each  zone  are  uniform  and  freight 
is  equalized  as  before,  to  the  plant  nearest  the  point  of  delivery. 
Asphalt  shingles  and  floor  tiles  furnish  examples  of  this  very  common 
type  of  structure.  A  further  degree  of  simplification  may  be  introduced 
by  the  adoption  of  a  standard  relationship  between  plant  prices  in 
different  zones;  the  price  in  one  zone  automatically  determines  plant 
prices  in  all  other  zones  by  the  application  of  a  simple  scheme  of  dis- 
counts or  additions.  Here  again  a  high  degree  of  price  uniformity 
between  rival  producers  is  readily  attainable  because  the  structure  is 
so  conventionalized. 

In  some  cases  sellers  find  it  expedient  to  set  certain  limits  to  the 
amount  of  freight  which  they  are  willing  to  absorb  in  connection  with 
equalization  schemes  of  this  sort.  The  limit  may  be  based  upon  the 
location  of  the. point  of  delivery,  the  alternative  shipping  point  for 
which  equalization  is  computed,  the  size  of  the  order,  or  the  actual 
cost  involved.  For  example,  unlimited  equalization  for  floor  tiles  is 
confined  to  a  few  items  such  as  the  standard  one-inch  hexagonal  tile; 
for  other  products  it  is  restricted  in  accordance  with  various  criteria. 
Equalization  may  be  allowed  only  on  sales  of  a  specified  quantity; 
thus  in  the  case  of  soda  ash  and  caustic  soda  the  practice  is  to  equalize 
freight  only  on  carload  shipments  presumably  because  the  higher 

"  These  comments  apply  equally  to  the  basing  point  and  zone  structures  described  subsequently. 

'•  There  is  some  evidence  that  this  practice  is  more  strictly  observed  on  "spot"  sales  than  on  contracts 
covering  a  period  of  time;  the  latter  type  of  transaction  seems  to  be  subject  to  some  variation,  especially  when 
the  buyer  can  exert  substantial  bargaining  pressure. 

i<  In  this  and  all  subsequent  discussion  the  phrase  "nearest  the  point  of  delivery"  should  be  understood 
In  terms  of  freicht  cost  and  not  of  physical  mileage.  In  other  words,  "nearest"  is  used  as  shorthand  for 
"having  lowest  shipping  costs  to." 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  279 

J.  c.  1.  rates  would  require  disproportionate  absorption.  Reservations 
of  this  kind  as  to  the  maximum  amount  of  freight  which  the  seller  is 
willing  to  absorb  have  the  effect  of  limiting  the  potential  sales  territory 
correspondingly  and  presumably  reflect  a  decision  that  sales  to  more 
distant  points  or  of  smaller  quantities  involve  an  unjustifiable  sacri- 
fice of  plant  net.  In  principle,  a  concern  may  be  willing  to  absorb 
freight  up  to  the  point  at  which  the  resulting  net  realization  is  adequate 
to  cover  little  more  than  direct  out-of-pocket  costs;  in  practice  con- 
ventional arrangements  within  an  industry  often  result  in  setting 
much  narrower  limits  to  freight  absorption. 

The  schemes  of  freight  equalization  so  far  considered  all  involve  the 
acceptance  of  reduced  plant  realizations  by  the  seller  on  sales  to  dis- 
tant points.  On  sales  to  immediately  surrounding  territory,  however, 
prices  remain  on  a  uniform  plant-net  basis  and  the  price  to  the  pur- 
chaser at  the  plant  door  wUl  be  lower  than  to  buyers  twenty  or  a 
hundred  miles  away.  In  other  words,  the  location  of  each  mill  governs 
the  price  structure  in  the  contiguous  area  and  the  erection  of  a  new 
plant  in  new  territory  wiU  be  reflected  automatically  by  a  change  in 
delivered  prices  in  that  territory. 

Basing-point  systems. — It  is  in  this  last  respect  that  schemes  of 
systematic  freight  equalization  differ  fundamentally  from  basing-point 
systems.  The  simplest  form  of  this  structure  is  the  single  basing- 
point  system.  Delivered  prices  at  any  point  in  the  United  States  are 
related  to  a  "base"  price  at  some  single  important  producing  center  and 
are  arrived  at  by  adding  to  this  base  price  the  freight  rate  (usually  for 
all-rail  shipment)  from  that  point  to  the  point  of  delivery.  This  was 
the  type  of  structure,  for  example,  which  prevailed  in  the  steel  industry 
between  1900  and  1926  except  for  certain  temporary  lapses  and  was 
known  as  "Pittsburgh  Plus."  As  the  name  implies,  the  delivered  price 
at  any  locality  was  the  base  price  at  Pittsburgh,  plus  freight  from 
Pittsburgh.  Thus  for  a  mill  located,  say,  at  Chicago,  the  delivered 
price  on  sales  at  the  mill  door  would  include  full  freight  from  Pitts- 
burgh; the  price  to  purchasers  farther  from  the  point  of  shipment  but 
nearer  freightwise  to  Pittsburgh  would  be  substantially  less.  The 
seller  would  charge  fictitious  freight  on  the  former  transaction  and  per- 
haps absorb  some  freight  on  the  latter. 

In  contrast  to  the  systems  of  freight  equalization  previously 
described,  which  may  have  developed  naturally  as  mills  enlarged  their 
territories,  there  is  evidence  that  one  of  the  important  considerations 
leading  to  the  adoption  of  the  basing-poinfc  system,  at  least  in  the 
case  of  the  steel  industry,  was  to  restrict  price  competition  as  far  as 
possible.  According  to  evidence  presented  to  the  Temporary  National 
Economic  Committee,  based  upon  an  earlier  investigation  by  the 
Federal  Trade  Commission,  the  Pittsburgh-Plus  system  originated 
under  the  following  circumstances: 

No  systematic  Pittsburgh-Plus  system  had  been  adopted  by  the  steel  producers 
at  the  time  of  Pittsburgh's  greatest  predominance  in  the  steel  industry  or  until 
after  1900.  From  1873  or  earlier  to  1903  steel  producers  attempted  generally 
with  some  success  to  fix  prices  for  steel  products  through  pools,  price-fixing  trade 
meetings,  and  later  on  through  what  are  known  as  the  "Gary  Dinners."  From 
1903  to  1909  the  Pittsburgh-Plus  system  of  quoting  and  selling  steel  products  was 
used  in  connection  with  and  as  a  basis  for  the  price-fixing  activities  of  the  steel 
producers.  From  1909  to  the  present  time,  with  minor  interruptions,  the  Pitts- 
burghrPlus  system  has  been  used  by  the  steel  producers  independently  of  such 


247  L4  9 — 41— No.  1 20 


280  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

pools,  price-fixing  trade  meetings,  and  Gary  Dinners  for  the  purpose  and  with  the 
effect  of  reaching  uniform  delivered  prices. 

In  1921,  with  the  advent  of  price  competition  on  plates,  shapes,  and  bars,  the 
Pittsburgh-Plus  system  was  discontinued  by  the  Chicago  district  mills  in  their 
sales  of  those  products,  but  not  in  their  sales  of  sheets  and  tin  plate  and  wire  and 
wire  products,  in  which  articles  in  that  district  and  everywhere  else  Pittsburgh- 
Plus  prices  still  prevail. 

The  wire  nail  producers,  including  the  Respondent,  American  Steel  &  Wire  Co., 
agreed  on  zone  prices  in  May  1898.  In  1904  the  large  wire  producers  agreed  to 
maintain  uniform  prices  by  means  of  the  Pittsburgh-Plus  system. 

Prior  to  the  year  1900  sheet  steel  was  not  sold  on  the  Pittsburgh-Plus  system, 
and  even  after  the  absorption  of  a  large  number  of  sheet  mills  by  the  American 
Sheet  Steel  Co.,  which  was  later  taken  over  by  Respondent,  American  Sheet  &  Tin 
Plate  Co.,  that  company  sold  its  sheets  in  the  Chicago  district  f.  o.  b.  its  mills  in 
that  district.  In  the  fall  of  1900,  however,  that  company  inaugurated  the  Pitts- 
burgh-Plus system  in  selling  its  sheets,  and  the  Respondent,  American  Sheet  & 
Tin  Plate  Co.,  has  followed  the  system  ever  since,  practically  without  exception. 

Prior  to  1900  to  1903  tin  mills  sold  their  products  generally  f.  o.  b.  mill,  but  after 
absorption  of  many  tin  mills  by  the  American  Tin  Plate  Co.,  which  was  shortly 
after  taken  over  by  Respondent,  American  Sheet  &  Tin  Plate  Co.,  that  company 
inaugurated  the  Pittsburgh-Plus  system  in  selling  its  tin  plate  from  its  various 
mills.  ' 

In  1903,  it  announced  as  to  its  Indiana  mills  that  tin  plate  would  no  longer  be 
fiold  f.  o.  b.  the  Indiana  mills  but  would  be  sold  thereafter  on  the  Pittsburgh-Plus 
system  because  of  the  higher  cost  of  production  at  the  Indiana  mills.  The 
respondent,  American  Sheet  &  Tin  Plate  Co.,  has  continued  the  Pittsburgh-Plus 
system  ever  since  on  tin  plate. '^ 

Further  excerpts  from  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  inquiry,  as 
reported  at  these  hearings,  include  the  testimony  of  Col.  Henry  Bope, 
who  was  vice  president  of  the  Carnegie  Corporation  after  it  was  taken 
over  by  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation.  This  testimony  throws 
further  light  upon  some  of  the  considerations  involved  in  the  adoption 
of  Pittsburgh  Plus. 

Q.  Going  back  to  the  original  organization,  what  connection  did  the  Pitts- 
burgh-base system  have  with  that? 

A.  (Colonel  Bope)  The  price  was  made,  based  upon  Pittsburgh,  because  the 
Carnegie  Bros.  &  Co.  were  the  largest  manufacturers,  and  it  was  felt  they  should 
have  the  say  as  to  what  the  price  should  be,  and  how  it  should  be  established  at 
the  main  point,  so  as  to  give  stability  of  prices,  which  had  been  fluctuating  all 
over  the  lot. 

Q.  By  that  do  you  mean  to  get  uniform  prices? 

A.  To  get  uniform  prices. 

Q.  Before  that  time  what  was  the  practice? 

A.  The  practice  was  eenerally  to  quote  f.  o.  b.  mills.  Every  mill  was  a  law 
unto  itself. 

Q.  And  the  difference  in  prices  between  the  mills,  did  that  amount  to  the 
freight  rate,  or  was  it  entirely  independent? 

A.  Each  mill  made  whatever  price  seemed  necessary  to  take  the  business. 

Q.  What  was  the  necessity  for  a  basing  point?  Could  they  maintain  prices 
without  a  basing  point? 

A.  No.  They  tried  it  once  in  1909  and  got  into  such  chaos  in  a  short  time  that 
the  mills  were  glad  to  get  back  to  the  old  base.  Every  system  has  to  have  some 
stabilizing  point,  and  Pittsburgh,  from  its  natural  location,  its  natural  advantages, 
and  everything  of  that  sort,  seemed  to  be  the  natural  basing  point. '^ 

The  maintenance  of  the  Pittsburgh-Plus  system  greatly  simplified 
the  preservation  of  price  uniformity  within  the  industry.  It  was 
manifestly  easier  to  make  sure  that  all  competitors  charged  the  same 
price  at  every  market  if  they  all  quoted  on  an  f.  o.  b.  Pittsburgh  basis 
than  would  be  true  if  each  quoted  f.  o.  b.  the  nearest  mill.  Since 
Jnost  concerns  preferred  to  avoid  price  competition,  this  was  con- 
sidered a  very  important  advantage. 

"  See  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  Hearings,  Part  27,  afternoon  session,  January  29, 1940. 
i«Ibld. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER  281 

As  an  industry  becomes  more  decentralized,  however,  the  main- 
tenance of  a  simple  basing-point  system  of  this  kind  becomes  increas- 
ingly difficult.  It  is  likely  to  incur  growing  resentment  from  buyers 
who  are  located  near  a  mill  distant  from  the  basing  point,  and  who  do 
not  see  why  they  should  be  called  upon  to  pay  fictitious  freight  from 
the  basing  point  upon  shipments  which  actually  travel  only  a  short 
•distance.  Moreover,  there  is  doubt  as  to  the  legality  of  single  basing 
point  systems  under  the  Sherman  and  Clayton  Acts  and  under  the 
Robinson-Patman  Act.  Consequently  there  has  been  a  shift  in 
many  industries  to  the  so-called  multiple  basing-point  system  in 
which  the  basing-point  principle  is  retained  but  the  number  of  basing 
points  is  increased  materially  to  reflect  the  establishment  of  important 
new  producing  centers.  Thus  the  steel  industry  shifted  from  the 
single  to  the  multiple  basing-point  system  in  1926,  at  least  partly 
because  of  pressure  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission. ^^  The  price 
actually  paid  by  the  buyer  for  delivery  at  any  point  then  becomes 
the  lowest  sum  of  the  price  at  any  basing  point  and  freight  from,  that 
basing  point. 

Since  an  important  aim  of  the  basing-point  system,  whether  single 
or  multiple,  is  the  maintenance  of  price  uniformity,  it  is  essential  to 
its  successful  operation  that  all  sellers  calculate  their  freight  charges 
in  the  same  way.  For  this  purpose  "freight  books"  are  frequently 
issued  by  leading  companies  or  by  trade  associations;  these  books 
indicate  the  freight  charges  which  are  to  be  used  in  calculating  the 
cost  of  sliipment  from  any  basing  point  to  any  important  market. 
The  rates  shown  in  these  books  do  not  necessarily  conform  in  every 
detail  with  actual  freight  charges  but  usually  follow  them  rather 
closely.  They  usually  seek  to  discourage  cheaper  means  of  trans- 
portation such  as  water  shipment  and  motor  truck,  since  to  do  this 
would  permit  the  buyer  to  effect  a  price  reduction  by  selecting  a 
more  economical  mode  of  transit-  and  thereby  to  interfere  with  the 
maintenance  of  uniformity.  In  the  steel  industry,  for  example,  al- 
though a  buyer  is  permitted  to  accept  plant  delivery  in  his  own  truck 
he  is  generally  required  to  pay  a  premium  amounting  to  35  percent 
of  the  cost  of  all  rail  delivery  for  this  privilege. ^^  The  entire  structure 
is  frankly  arbitrary,  and  is  predicated  at  least  in  part  on  the  assump- 
tion that  price  competition  is  not  desirable.  It  was  admitted  by 
President  Fairless,  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  that  the 
effect  of  the  basing-point  system,  if  it  were  always  faithfully  observed, 
would  be  to  eliminate  price  competition  in  the  industry  entirely. 
According  to  Mr.  Fairless: 

It  seems  to  me  that  for  all  practical  purposes  and  for  the  conservation  of  time, 
which  I  believe  is  important  to  all  of  us,  we  will  concede,  if  that  is  the  point  that 
you  are  trying  to  make,  that  if  base  prices  as  announced  were  followed  in  every 
transaction,  and  that  the  nearest  basing  point  to  the  consumer  governed,  and 
that  the  rail  freight  was  added  from  that  point,  and  the  delivered  price  arrived 
at  in  that  manner,  there  wouldn't  be  any  competition  in  the  steel  industry.  It 
would  be  a  one-price  industry,  pure  and  simple.** 

However,  in  common  with  most  other  systems  of  pricing,  discounts 
and  concessions  from  the  nominal  price  level  are  granted  sellers  under 
certain  circumstances.  Such  concessions  are  most  common  during  a 
buyers'  market  when  the  pressure  to  obtain  business  is  most  acute. 

"  A  cease  and  desist  order  was  issued  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  against  the  Linited  States  Steel 
Corporation  on  July  21,  1924,  Docket  No.  760. 
>*  See  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  Hearings,  Part  27,  afternoon  session,  January  26,  1940. 
"Ibid. 


2g2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Although  the  ba sing-point  system  has  been  described  in  terms  of  the 
steel  industry,  it  should  not  be  inferred  that  this  is  the  only  important 
area  in  which  it  is  encountered.  Cast-iron  soil  pipe,  for  example,  has 
been  sold  on  the  basis  of  a  single  basing  point  in  Birmingham,  Ala. 
The  pulp,  sugar,  cement,  and  lead  industries  all  use  multiple  basing- 
point  systems.  In  some  cases  basing-point  systems  are  observed  with 
respect  to  part  of  the  market  only;  for  instance,  benzol  is  priced 
f.  o.  b.  Minnequa,  Colo.,  only  on  sales  in  the  region  "Omaha  and 
West"  and  gasoline  is  sold  f.  o.  b.  Tulsa  only  in  parts  of  the  Midwest. 
In  each  case  the  system  may  be  adjusted  to  the  peculiar  needs  of  the 
industry  involved  and  some  of  its  more  important  variations  will  be 
described  in  the  following  chapter. 

"Fostage  stamp"  and  zone  systems. — For  all  the  geographic  struc- 
tures so  far  considered,  delivered  prices  at  any  point  are  arrived  at  by 
taking  some  combination  of  plant  price  and  shipping  costs,  though  as 
was  pointed  out,  the  addition  for  shipping  charges  is  often  arbitrary 
rather  than  actual.  Delivered  prices  vary  from  locality  to  locality 
depending  upon  its  distance  freightwise  from  whatever  point  is  the 
actual  or  nominal  base  of  shipment. 

There  is  a  second  major  tj^'pe  of  structure  which  does  not  display 
any  such  point-to-point  variation  but  in  which  delivered  -prices  are 
uniform  either  throughout  the  entire  United  States  or  within  certain 
defined  geographic  zones.  This  may  be  accomplished  either  by  quot- 
ing delivered  prices  directly,  or  by  quoting  f.  o.  b.  prices  and  allowing 
full  freight. 

Uniform  delivered  prices  thioughout  the  United  States  are  most 
commonly  encountered  when  shipping  costs  are  relatively  minor  in 
relation  to  the  value  of  the  commodity.  They  are  frequent  in  the 
case  of  nationally  advertised  consumer  goods,  particularly  where  some 
effort  is  made  by  the  manufacturer  to  control  resale  prices  as  for 
nationally  advertised  drugs  and  cosmetics.  When  the  manufacturer 
advertises  a  list  price  for  his  product  or  fixes  minimum  resale  prices  in 
accordance  with  State  price  maintenance  laws,  there  is  an  obvious  ad- 
vantage in  geographic  price  uniformity,  since  otherwise  distributors  in 
one  section  of  the  coimtry  would  be  forced  to  accept  smaller  mark-ups 
than  those  in  other  sections.  Even  in  the  absence  of  resale  price 
maintenance,  delivered  price  uniformity  may  be  favored  as  a  means 
of  reducing  the  incentive  to  distributors  to  encroach  on  each  other's 
territory .^°  Uniform  delivered  prices  are  also  quoted  for  some  indus- 
trial products  when  freight  is  a  minor  element;  this  practice  is  fol- 
lowed, for  example,  in  the  case  of  aluminum.^' 

>»  Thus,  according  to  a  recent  article  in  the  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics; 

"The  policy  of  quoting  prices  freight  allowed  is  frequently  said  by  manufacturers  to  be  used  in  order  to 
place  their  distributors  in  adjoining  territories  on  'an  equal  competitive  basis';  and  further,  at  times  to  give 
the  wholesale  trade  the  same  mark-up  in  a  policy  of  maintaining  national,  uniform,  resale  prices.  With  a 
quoting  of  prices  f.  o.  b.  factory,  freight  allowed  to  jobbers'  warehouses,  any  given  jobber  would  be  at  a 
disadvantage  in  entering  another's  territory  even  though  he  had  general  salesmen  in  that  field.  Thus  a 
manufacturer  of  air-rifle  shot  in  assigning  a  reason  for  the  use  of  the  freight  allowed  policy  said:  'To  make 
landed  cost  to  distributors  everywhere  the  same  and  thus  localize  each  jobber's  business  and  keep  far-away 
jobbers  from  entering  others'  territory.'  Other  typical  answers  of  various  manufacturers  were  'to  put  all 
distributors  on  the  same  cost  basis  regardless  of  location,  so  that  they  can  compete  on  an  equal  basis  of  cost'; 
'to  give  jobbers  the  same  cost';  and  'so  that  distributors  of  our  products  in  adjoining  territories  will  be  on  an 
equal  competitive  basis.' 

"The  desire  of  manufacturers  to  give  the  wholesale  trade  the  same  mark-up  in  a  program  of  national, 
uniform  resale  prices  is  illustrated  by  the  following  str.tement  recently  sent  by  a  glass  manufacturer  to  its 
Jobbers.  '  •  •  •  Glass  Works  will  carry  the  freight  burden,  enabling  jobbers  to  operate  with  a  fixed 
gross  profit  uninfluenced  by  varying  freight  rates,  undisturbed  by  their  fluctuations.  Suggested  retail 
prices  will  be  the  same  for  east  and  west.  Allowed  freight  eliminates  the  need  for  a  differential.' "  (The 
Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  vol.  LIV,  February  1940,  "The  'Freight  Allowed'  Method  of  Price  Quota- 
tion" by  Vernon  A.  Mund,  pp.  238,  239.) 

M  According  to  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  rail  freight  during  1936  represented  3.24  percent  of 
the  value  of  aluminum  at  destination. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  283 

A  distinction  may  be  made  between  commodities  which  are  de- 
hvered  at  the  same  nrice  (or  on  which  full  freight  is  allowed)  to  any 
destination  in  the  United  States  and  those  for  which  this  privilege 
extends  only  to  established  distributing  or  jobbing  centers,  with  pur- 
chasers not  located  at  such  centers  being  required  to  pay  the  expense 
of  further  transportation.  The  former  practice  is  more  commonly 
associated  with  light  goods,  such  as  pharmaceutical  products  and  the 
latter  with  heavier  merchandise,  such  as  building  materials,  but  prac- 
tice is  by  no  means  consistent.  Since  in  general  most  important  con- 
suming areas  are  recognized  as  distributing  points,  delivered  price 
uniformity  at  such  points  is  often  equivalent  to  uniformity  for  the 
bulk  of  the  market. 

In  some  cases  uniform  delivered  prices  may  be  combined  with  plant 
pricing  in  such  a  way  that  they  act  as  a  ceiling  to  the  market,  rather 
than  as  a  universal  price.  Thus  carbon  black  in  less-than-c  irload  lots 
can  be  purchased  either  f.  o.  b.  plant,  or,  at  the  buyer's  option,  it  will 
be  delivered  anywhere  in  the  United  States  for  a  fixed  premium. 

Instead  of  nation-wide  uniformity,  delivered  prices  may  be  kept 
constant  throughout  certain  defined  geographic  zones.  The  extent 
of  these  zones  varies  considerably;  one  may  take  in  all  the  area  east 
or  west  of  the  Mississippi  or  east  or  west  of  the  Rockies,  or  it  may  be 
restricted  to  the  limits  of  a  single  State  or  part  of  a  State.  An  impor- 
tant factor  is  again  the  relative  cost  of  shipment;  where  this  is  high, 
the  zones  are  likely  to  be  narrower  than  when  it  is  low.  As  in  the  case 
of  basing  point  systems,  zone  systems  often  reflect  the  historical 
development  of  the  industry.  Thus  where  scattered  sources  of  supply 
are  competing  within  certain  geographically  limited  markets,  there 
may  be  a  tendency  for  price  uniformity  within  such  markets  to 
exist.  Such  dividing  lines  as  the  Mississippi  River  or  the  Rocky 
Mountains  may  be  explained  both  by  the  gradual  extension  of  markets 
into  areas  previously  untapped  and  by  the  nature  of  the  railroad 
freight  rate  structure  itself. 

There  are  numerous  examples  of  zone  systems  in  majiy  different 
kinds  of  industries.  Many  chemicals  such  as  carbon  black,  carbon 
tetrachloride,  and  anhydrous  ammouia  are  priced  on  a  zone  basis. 
A  highly  developed  system  of  19  zones  and  many  subzones  and  even 
subdivisions  of  subzones  is  used  in  the  market  for  fertilizer.  Zone 
systems  are  observed  in  the  sale  of  paper  with  the  number  of  zones 
varyiug  widely  for  different  products.  Thus,  there  are  10  zones  for 
newsprint  and  4  for  fine  papers.  As  in  the  case  of  uniform  delivered 
prices,  zone  prices  sometimes  apply  to  any  destination  within  the 
zone  and  sometimes  only  to  distributing  or  jobbing  centers. 

In  most  cases,  the  boundaries  of  zones  have  become  generally 
recognized  throughout  the  industry  and  are  observed  by  all  com- 
peting sellers,  except  insofar  as  prices  may  be  cut  on  particular 
transactions  in  order  to  obtain  a  desired  order.  However,  this  is 
not  always  the  case.  For  example,  most  refrigerator  manufacturers 
maintain  a  zone  system  for  the  retail  markets  of  their  products,  but 
zone  boundaries  are  not  the  same  for  all  producers.  Moreover,  kince 
the  beginning  of  1940  one  manufacturer  has  recently  announced 
uniform  prices  for  the  entire  region  east  of  the  Rockies. 

Sometimes  zone  systems  apply  at  one  market  level,  but  not  at 
others.  Thus,  certain  electric  refrigerators  are  sold  to  wholesale 
distributors  on  an  f.  o.  b.  plant  basis,  and  distributors  resell  to  retail 


284  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

dealers  on  a  zone  basis.  The  same  practice  seems  to  be  true  in  the 
case  of  fine  paper. 

Zone  limits  may  be  used  to  set  a  maximum  price  for  the  area 
rather  than  a  fixed  price  applicable  to  all  customers.  For  example, 
buyers  of  fertilizers  who  happen  to  be  located  near  certain  ports  are 
able  to  buy  on  what  amounts  to  an  f.  o.  b.  port  basis;  prices  increase 
with  the  distance  from  the  port  until  the  maximum  for  the  zone  is 
reached;  beyond  this  point  there  is  no  further  advance.  Frequently 
zone  prices  apply  on  purchases  of  a  specified  minimum  quantity  only, 
usually  a  carload.  This  is  true,  for  example,  of  fertilizer,  carbon  black, 
and  numerous  other  products.  Sometimes  the  situation  is  reversed, 
with  the  zone  structure  applying  to  small  shipments  only,  while  some 
other  basis  is  used  for  larger  orders.  For  instance,  caustic  soda  and 
soda  ash  in  carload  lots  are  sold  freight  equalized,  but  for  1.  c.  1,  lots 
prices  are  on  a  zone  basis. 

The  relationship  between  prices  in  different  zones  may  or  may  not 
be  fixed  by  custom.  In  the  case  of  newsprint,  for  example,  the  price 
in  any  zone  can  be  derived  by  applying  a  premium  or  deduction  to 
the  quoted  price  in  an  accepted  ''base"  zone.  A  similar  practice  is 
followed  in  the  case  of  many  other  commodities.  On  the  other  hand, 
zone  differentials  may  vary  considerably  from  time  to  time  with  the 
price  in  each  area  determined  by  conditions  in  that  area. 

One  further  variant  of  the  zone  type  of  structure  which  is  commonly 
encountered  is  the  "free  delivery  zone."  In  the  case  of  many  kinds 
of  apparel,  for  example,  such  as  women's  dresses,  there  is  no  charge 
for  delivery  within  the  metropolitan  area  in  which  the  garment  is 
manufactured.  The  prices  in  all  other  areas  are  on  an  f.  o.  b.  plant 
basis.  In  some  instances  the  free  delivery  zone  may  be  dictated  by 
competitive  considerations  rather  than  by  the  location  of  the  produc- 
ing plant.  Thus  some  manufacturers  of  men's  shirts  make  no  charge 
for  delivery  in  the  New  York  City  area,  even  though  their  plants  may 
be  at  some  distance  from  that  city.  As  is  evident  from  these  examples, 
the  existence  of  a  free  delivery  zone  or  zones  does  not  necessarily  imply 
the  observance  of  a  zone  structure  in  other  areas. 

Buyer  dominated  structures — equalization  at  the  -point  oj  origin. — 
So  far,  geographic  price  structures  have  been  described  in  relation  to 
the  marketing  policies  of  sellers.  It  has  been  suggested  that  sporadic 
freight  absorption  may  reflect  a  concern's  desire  to  extend  sales  into 
an  area  in  which  a  rival  enjoys  a  freight  advantage,  while  some  of  the 
more  conventionalized  forms  of  structure  may  represent  efforts  to 
limit  or  eliminate  the  influence  of  price  competition  as  a  market  factor. 
In  the  latter  situation,  particularly,  this  has  involved  the  implicit 
assumption  that  decisions  as  to  price  policy  were  largely  in  the  hands 
of  sellers  and  that  buyers  either  could  do  little  to  alter  such  decisions 
or  else  acquiesce  in  them  as  mutually  beneficial.  While  this  assump- 
tion is  obviously  an  oversimplification,  it  probably  does  not  materially 
misrepresent  the  usual  situation  in  most  industrial  markets.  The 
breakdowns  of  structure  which  occur  during  a  depressed  buyers' 
market  merely  emphasize  the  rule. 

There  are,  however,  numerous  sectors  of  the  market  in  which  buyers, 
and  not  sellers,  normally  hold  the  balance  of  power.  In  such  cases  it 
may  be  to  the  interest  of  these  buyers  to  avoid  competing  among 
themselves  in  their  purchases  of  raw  materials.     Just  as  price  competi- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  285 

tion  among  sellers  may  force  prices  down,  so  price  competition  among 
buyers  may  bid  prices  up.  There  is  some  evidence  that  geographic 
price  structures  may  occasionally  be  adapted  to  prevent  the  latter  as 
well  as  the  former  type  of  price  competition.  Under  such  circum- 
stances prices  will  be  quoted  and  published  by  buyers  rather  than  by 
sellers,  and  they  will  be  equalized  at  the  point  of  shipment  rather  than 
at  the  point  of  delivery.  Clear  instances  of  this  kind  are  uncommon, 
but  they  do  occur.  Two  such  cases — nonferrous  scrap  metal  and,  at 
least  until  recently,  cottonseed — will  be  described  in  the  next  chapter. 
Crude  petroleum  is  another  possible  example. 

Unsystematic  price  variation. — Finally,  there  are  types  of  geographic 
price  variation  which  do  not  fit  into  any  of  these  more  or  less  clear-cut 
patterns.  For  example,  prices  in  different  markets  may  be  largely 
out  of  the  control  of  the  seller,  as  in  the  case  of  fresh  fruits  or  vegetables 
sold  at  auction  or  on  consignment.  Special  competitive  situations 
may  exist  in  particular  markets  which  make  it  necessary  to  deviate 
from  the  general  practice  on  sales  in  those  areas.  Thus  where  imports 
are  competing  with  domestic  sources  of  supply,  prices  at  important 
ports  of  entry  may  bear  no  direct  relation  to  the  general  domestic 
price  structure.  For  example,  because  of  the  competition  of  imports 
the  price  of  cement  in  New  York  is  not  related  to  the  general  basing- 
point  structure  of  that  industry ;  in  the  language  of  the  industry,  New 
York  is  an  "arbitrary"  point. 

In  practice,  the  types  of  structure  which  have  been  considered  are 
subject  to  almost  infinite  variation  and  combination  to  meet  the 
peculiar  needs  of  specific  markets.  Some  of  these  will  be  illustrated 
in  the  followdng  chapter,  which  describes  the  patterns  of  price  variation 
actually  found  in  various  sectors  of  the  American  economy. 


CHAPTER  II 
GEOGRAPHIC  PRACTICES  IN  AMERICAN  MARKETS 

METHODS    OF    ANALYSIS 

The  preceding  chapter  included  a  description  of  most  of  the  more 
common  types  of  price  structure  encountered  in  American  markets. 
In  the  following  pages,  practices  actually  observed  in  connection  with 
the  sale  of  a  wide  range  of  commodities  are  described.  The  com- 
modities discussed  were  selected  partly  on  the  basis  of  availability  of 
data  and  partly  m  an  effort  to  include  a  representative  group  illustrat- 
ing a  wide  diversity  of  market  situations. 

The  analysis  is  extensive  and  not  intensive.  It  has  not  been 
possible  to  consider  the  geographic  price  structure  for  any  commodity 
in  full  detail,  since  to  do  so  would  far  transcend  the  limitations  of 
time,  personnel,  and  space  which  have  been  allotted  to  this  study. 
The  primary  purpose  of  this  study,  as  stated  in  the  preface,  was  to 
afford  some  indication  of  the  extent  to  which  particular  kinds  of 
geographic  price  structure  are  observed  in  different  sectors  of  industry 
and  in  the  economy  generally,  and  it  is  in  the  light  of  this  purpose 
that  the  following  discussion  should  be  interpreted. 

The  data  upon  which  the  analysis  is  based  have  been  compiled 
from  a  wide  variety  of  sources.  The  most  important  of  these  was  di- 
rect contact  with  members  of  industry  and  trade  association  officials. 
In  addition,  much  information  was  obtained  from  experts  in  other 
agencies  of  the  Government,  from  published  studies  of  the  Federal 
Trade  Commxission,  the  Department  of  Agriculture,  and  other  Federal 
departments,  from  trade  publications,  and  from  records  of  the  Whole- 
sale Price  Division  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.  Information 
with  regard  to  steel  and  petroleum  products  is  primarily  based  upon 
testimony  presented  at  hearings  before  the  Temporary  National 
Economic  Corftmittee.  Data  relating  to  building  materials  largely 
reflect  the  results  of  a  detailed  field  study  which  has  been  conducted 
by  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  Studies  Section  of 
the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.  In  addition,  various  reports  of  the 
National  Recovery  Administration  proved  useful  as  source  material 
in  casting  added  light  upon  current  practices,  but  they  were  not  relied 
upon  per  se  as  evidence  of  existing  geographic  price  structures.  Some 
information  was  also  obtained  from  a  recent  study  by  Vernon  A. 
Mund,  published  in  the  Harvard  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics} 

This  chapter  considers  commodities  and  broad  commodity  groups 
in  the  following  order: 

Agricultural  commodities. 

Food  and  kindred  products. 

Textiles  and  textile  products. 

'  Op.  cit. 
286 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  287 

Leather  and  its  .major  products. 

Tobacco  products. 

Steel  and  steel  products. 

Lumber  and  its  products. 

Turpentine. 

Building  materials  other  than  steel  and  lumber. 

Furniture. 

Chemicals. 

Drugs,  cosmetics,  and  toiletries. 

Fertilizer. 

Paper  and  pulp  industries. 

Passenger  automobiles. 

Agricultural  implements  and  machinery. 

Machinery  and  related  products,  other  than  automotive  and 
agricultural. 

Electrical  household  equipment. 

Nonferrous  metals. 

Petroleum  and  its  products. 

Bituminous  coal. 

These  analyses  of  conditions  in  specific  markets  are  followed  by  a 
summary  of  the  major  distinct  types  of  geographic  price  structure, 
indicating  the  products  and  sectors  of  industry  for  which  each  was 
encountered. 

AGRICULTURAL    COMMODITIES 

The  geographic  price  structures  of  agricultural  commodities  are 
rarely  as  well  defined  as  those  for  the  products  of  industry.  The 
reasons  for  this  are  obvious.  The  number  of  sellers  in  any  market  is 
usually  so  great  that  no  one  of  them  can  exert  any  appreciable  in- 
fluence upon  the  prices  which  hei  receives  for  hi^  crops.  Since  the 
price  itself  is  largely  beyond  his  control,  there  is  little  opportunity 
for  the  development  of  any.  rigid  conventional  practices  regarding 
collateral  terms  of  sale,  such  as  the  payment  of  freight  charges.  At 
the  same  time  there  are  many  different  kinds  of  buyers  in  the  market, 
purchasing  under  different  conditions  and  for  different  ultimate  uses 
and  destinations. 

Nevertheless  there  are  certain  broad  price  relationships  and  cer- 
tain customs  with  regard  to  the  payment  of  freight  costs  which  have 
displayed  a  degree  of  persistence  and  ^hich  apply  to  substantial 
sectors  of  the  market.  In  contrast  with  the  geographic  price  struc- 
tures which  prevail  for  manufactured  commodities,  however,  these 
relationships  usually  represent  inevitable  adjustments  to  character- 
istics inherent  in  the  market,  rather  than  business  policy  decisions, 
although  the  influence  of  the  latter  may  be  revealed  in  some  minor 
details. 

In  general,  the  pattern  of  geographic  variation  of  the  prices  re- 
ceived by  producers  of  agricultural  commodities  is  governed  in  the 
first  instance  by  the  location  of  major  terminal  markets.  In  some 
cases,  as  for  fresh  fruits  and  vegetables,  such  markets  exist  at  most 
important  centers  of  consumption,  which  also  serve  as  points  of  dis- 
tribution for  the  surrounding  territory.  For  staple  commodities,  and 
particularly  those  traded  in  organized  exchanges  or  in  futures  markets, 


288  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

these  terminal  markets  are  more  narrowly  concentrated  and  represent 
primarily  points  at  which  the  product  is  collected  for  distribution 
throughout  the  United  States. 

In  surplus  producing  areas,  that  is  in  those  sections  which  raise 
more  of  the  product  than  can  be  used  locally,  the  price  received  by 
growers  tends  to  be  determined  by  the  price  prevailing  at  the  terminal 
market,  less  the  cost  of  transportation  to  that  market.  In  deficit 
areas  which  raise  less  than  they  consume,  the  reverse  relationship 
will  be  encountered  and  growers  may  receive  a  price  limited  by  the 
terminal  market  price,  plus  the  cost  of  transportation.  For  export 
commodities,  such  as  wheat,  the  controlling  element  will  be  not  only 
the  domestic  requirements  of  any  area  but  also  export  demand. 

In  both  surplus  and  deficit  areas  the  price  relationships  just  des- 
cribed are  limiting  relationships  which  may  not  actually  conform 
with  the  existing  pattern  of  variation  at  any  time.  Thus  in  a  surplus 
area  the  prices  are  not  likely  to  fall  below  the  terminal  market  price 
less  freight ,  and  in  deficit  areas  they  will  not  rise  above  terminal 
market  price  plus  freight,  because  in  either  event  it  would  become 
profitable  to  ship  to  or  from  the  terminal  market.  However,  there 
may  be  many  conditions  which  would  cause  variation  within  these 
limits,  such  as  the  avaUabUity  of  advantageous  freight  rates  for 
direct  shipment  from  a  surplus  to  a  deficit  area  without  passing 
through  recognized  terminal  markets.  For  some  commodities,  such 
as  wheat,  there  may  also  be  "mUling-in-transit"  freight  rates  which 
combine  the  cost  of  shipping  the  wheat  to  the  flour  mill  and  the  flour 
to  its  ultimate  destination  into  a  single  charge,  thereby  permitting  a 
further  narrowing  of  the  differential  between  the  terminal  market 
price  of  wheat  and  the  amount  received  by  the  grower.^  A  somewhat 
similar  situation  applies  through  "storage-in-transit"  rates  for  such 
products  as  potatoes  which  make  it  possible  to  store  the  product  en 
route  from  farm  to  market  without  any  equivalent  increase  in  the 
cost  of  shipping. 

Another  important  influence  upon  the  geographic  price  structure 
of  agricultural  commodities  is  the  manner  in  which  they  are  marketed. 
They  can  either  be  sold  by  the  farmer  or  local  dealer  on  an  f.  o.  b. 
basis  at  the  point  of  shipment,  or  they  can  be  sent  directly  to  the 
terminal  market  on  a  consignment  basis.  The  latter  practice  is  com- 
mon in  the  case  of  fresh  fruits  and  vegetables  and  for  the  former  the 
price  to  be  paid  at  the  market  is  determined  at  organized  auctions. 
Under  such  circumstances  the  grower  or  local  dealer  does  not  know 
what  his  net  return  will  be  until  after  the  auction  has  been  held.  In 
extreme  cases,  it  is  even  possible  that  the  price  received  at  destination 
will  not  be  sufficient  to  cover  the  full  cost  of  shipment.  Even  on 
sales  "which  are  nominally  on  an  f;  o.  b.  basis,  guarantees  against 
price  declines  during  transit  may  be  required,  which  result  in  a  con- 
dition not  materially  different  from  that  for  consignment  transactions. 

The  manner  in  which  these  general  considerations  affect  the  market 
for  10  important  agricultural  commodities — wheat,  com,  oats,  cotton, 
potatoes,  hogs,  wool,  butter  fat,  eggs,  and  chickens — is  revealed  in  an 
analysis  prepared  by  the  Department  of  Agriculture.^  The  way  in 
which  prices  grade  down  in  surplus  producing  areas  and  up  in  deficit 

>  Seep.  289  below. 

«  U.  S.  Department  of  Agriculture,  Regional  Variations  in  Prices  Received  by  Farmers,  1925-34,  for  Ten 
Selected  Commodities,  May  1939. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  289 

areas  is  clearly  illustrated  in  a  series  of  10  contour  maps  included  in 
this  publication,  which  shows  the  actual  average  prices  received  by 
farmers  for  these  products  in  different  regions  for  the  period  1925-34. 

The  detailed  characteristics  of  the  markets  for  a  few  important 
products  are  described  below. 

Wheat. — The  geographic  price  structure  of  wheat  is  largely  affected 
by  the  existence  of  six  major  terminal  markets;  Kansas  City  and 
Omaha  for  hard  winter  wheat,  St.  Louis  for  soft  red  winter  wheat, 
Minneapolis  and  Duluth  for  spring  wheat  and  durum,  and  Seattle  for 
western  white  winter  wheat.  Spot  prices  in  each  of  these  markets 
are  constantly  changing,  partly  under  the  influence  of  fluctuations  in 
futures  markets.  GeneraUy  speaking,  prices  at  grain  elevators  lo- 
cated elsewhere  than  at  terminal  markets  move  in  direct  response  to 
terminal  market  prices.  In  major  wheat  producing  areas,  in  which 
the  crop  is  more  than  adequate  to  take  care  of  any  local  requirements, 
local  prices  will  tend  to  be  less  than  terminal  market  prices  by  an 
amount  equal  to  the  cost  of  shipment  and  handling  to  the  most 
advantageously  located  terminal  market.^  In  a  sense  this  may  be 
compared  with  a  basing  point  system  in  reverse,  with  the  prices  at 
any  point  being  the  difference  between  the  base  price  and  the  cost  of 
shipment  rather  than  their  sum. 

This  situation  exists,  however,  only  in  those  areas  where  the  supply 
of  wheat  for  sale  exceeds  the  demand  from  local  mills.  In  regions 
where  the  mill  demand  exceeds  the  local  supply,  the  reverse  con- 
dition may  occur  and  price  be  determined  by  adding  freight  to  the 
terminal  market  quotation,  rather  than  subtracting  it.  This  is 
generally  true,  for  example,  on  the  eastern  seaboard. 

Some  regions  may  be  border-line  in  character,  with  the  crop  ex- 
ceeding demand  during  good  ye^rs  and  being  inadequate  to  meet  it 
during  poor  years,  and  prices  will  reflect  these  changes.  In  Colorado, 
for  example,  the  price  tends  to  fluctuate  between  the  Kansas  City 
piice  plus  freight,  when  the-  crop  is  poor  and  the  Kansas  City  price 
minus  freight,  when  the  crop  is  good. 

One  important  modification  of  the  structure  described  relates  to 
the  availability  of  "miUing-in-transit"  freight  rates.  A  substantial 
amount  of  wheat  is  sold  under  an  arrangement  whereby  the  freight 
rate  on  wheat  shipped  to  a  flour  mill  and  then  reshipped  as  flour  to 
its  ultimate  destination  is  based  upon  the  through  rate  from  the 
point  of  origin  of  the  wheat  to  the  point  of  destination  of  the  flour, 
rather  than  upon  the  individual  hauls  of  the  wheat  and  of  the  flour. 
This  "milling-in-transit"  rate  varies  with  the  freight  zone  or  area  in 
which  the  wheat  originates  and  the  zone  in  which  the  flour  terminates. 
Within  these  zones  or  areas  the  freight  rate  is  identical;  in  other 
words  it  is  a  "blanket  rate."  For  example,  for  wheat  raised  in  the 
Chicago  area,  there  may  be  three  possible  blanket  rates  depending 
upon  the  origin  and  destination;  a  trans-Mississippi  rate,  a  rate  for 
the  State  of  Illinois,  and  a  rate  for  the  territory  east  of  Illinois. 

The  price  which  the  miller  can  pay  for  wheat  at  any  elevator,  there- 
fore, depends  upon  the  location  of  his  flour  market  and  may  be  sub- 
stantially higher  than  the  spot  price  at  the  terminal  market,  less 

*  Thus,  according  to  a  study  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  "Grain  prices  paid  in  the  country  to 
farmers  under  normal  competitive  conditions  among  country  elevators  are  based  primarily  on  the  'cash' 
or  'to  arrive'  prices  at  terminal  markets  for  the  same  kind  and  grade,  less  freight,  terminal  handling  charges 
and  the  country  dealer's  gross  margin."  (Federal  Trade  Commission,  Agricultural  Income  Inquiry,  1937, 
Pt.  I,  p.  328.) 


290  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

straight  haul  freight.  It  would  be  most  accurate  to  say  that  these 
two  situations  set  the  limits  within  which  prices  in  any  surplus  pro- 
ducing area  wiU  vary.  Prices  will  not  at  any  time  fall  appreciably 
below  the  terminal  market  less  freight,  because  if  they  did,  it  would 
become  profitable  to  ship  to  the  terminal  market.  On  the  other 
hand,  millers  may  often  be  in  a  position  to  bid  above  this  limiting 
quotation  when  they  see  the  possibility  of  advantageous  "in-transit" 
freight  arrangements. 

According  to  the  Department  of  Agriculture,  the  lowest  average 
price  received  by  farmers  for  wheat  during  the  decade  1925-34  was 
in  the  surplus  producing  area  in  eastern  Wyoming.  The  price  in  this 
area  was  about  80  cents,  or  between  15  and  20  cents  below  the  prices 
at  the  major  midwestern  terminal  markets.  Another  low  area  was 
Idaho,  in  which  the  price  of  about  85  cents  was  some  15  cents  below 
the  Seattle  level.  Highest  recorded  average  prices— $1 .30  per  bushel — 
were  in  the  extreme  southeastern  States,  Georgia  and  Alabama,  which 
produced  little  wheat  and  are  furthest  freightwise  from  the  terminal 
markets.** 

Milk. — The  price  of  fluid  mUk  is  subject  to  minimum  price  deter- 
mination by  the  Department  of  Agriculture.  The  United  States  is 
divided  into  approximately  25  marketing  areas,  and  in  each  of  these 
areas  minimum  prices  are  established  by  classes  of  milk.  In  general^ 
these  prices  apply  to  delivery  at  the  market  so  that  the  net  return  to 
the  farmer  will  vary  with  his  distance  from  the  market  to  which  he 
ships  and  with  the  arrangements  which  he  can  make  for  transporta- 
tion. The  difference  between  the  price  at  the  market  and  the  net 
return  to  the  farmer  may  be  substantial;  thus  for  four  urban  market 
areas  the  delivered  cost  to  dealer  during  October  1935  averaged  $0,053 
per  quart,  while  the  net  return  to  farmer  was  $0,045.® 

Cattle. — The  marketing  of  cattle  is  centered  in  Chicago  and  Kansas 
City  and  prices  at  these  two  important  centers  are  closely  related  to 
each  other  because  of  the  ability  of  packers  to  shift  their  purchases 
from  one  market  to  the  other.  Net  return  to  producers  in  major 
producing  areas,  therefore,  usually  represents  the  difference  between 
prices  at  these  terminal  markets  and  cost  of  shipping  cattle  to  them. 

Potatoes. — There  is  a  wide  variety  of  different  practices  observed  in 
the  sale  of  potatoes  with  regard  to  the  burden  of  transportation  costs. 
Practices  vary  for  early  and  late  potatoes,  with  the  producing  area, 
the  method  of  financing  the  crop,  the  channel  of  distribution,  the  grade 
of  the  product,  and  many  other  factors.  In  some  cases,  sales  are  on  a 
straight  f.  o.  b.  basis,  m  others  there  is  a  guarantee  against  price  decline 
during  transit,  and  in  still  others,  particularly  with  regard  to  potatoes 
of  lower  grade,  sales  are  on  a  consignment  basis.  These  differences  in 
practice  are  described  in  detail  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  in 
its  agricultural  income  inquiry.  A  few  relevant  quotations  from  this 
report  follow  and  illustrate  the  diversity  of  possible  situations. 

METHODS   OF   SALE   BY   GROWERS 

The  practices  which  exist  in  connection  with  the  disposition  by  the  grower  of 
potatoes  vary  considerably  in  the  several  commercial  producing  areas  under  con- 
sideration. Fundamentally,  these  differences  stem  from  the  single  question  of 
whether  or  not  the  grower  had  to  depend  upon  outside  sources  for  a  part  or  all 

«  Op.  cit.,  p.  2. 

•  Federal  Trade  Commission,  Agricultural  Income  Inquiry,  1937,  Part  I,  p.  121. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


291 


of  the  capital  necessary  for  financing  the  production  of  his  crop.  Where. the 
grower  receives  an  advance  it  is  almost  invariably  accompanied  by  some  control 
over  the  disposition  of  the  crop.     *     *     * 

Where  the  grower  is  able  to  finance  his  crop  without  resort  to  outside  agencies, 
he  is,  of  course,  free  to  dispose  of  it  in  whatever  manner  he  chooses.  The  ordi- 
nary channels  utilized  are  direct  sales  by  the  grower  to  truckers,  to  local  dealers, 
sales  in  carlots  to  terminal  market  receivers  or  chain  stores,  and  shipments  on 
<!onsignment  to  commission  merchants. 

In  Florida:  The  Florida  crop  is  marketed  largely  on  an  f.  o.  b.  basis,  except  in 
the  case  of  potatoes  grading  lower  than  U.  S.  No.  1,  or  shipments  made  after  other 
commercial  producing  areas  have  begun  to  compete  strongly  with  Florida  potatoes 
in  the  terminal  markets.  In  the  exceptions  just  mentioned,  shipments  are  usually 
on  a  consignment  basis  and  are  sold  as  circumstances  permit.     *     *     * 

In  South  Carolina:  *  *  *  jjj  ^j^g  Charleston  area  it  is  estimated  that  about 
70  percent  of  all  sales  are  made  on  an  f.  o.  b.  basis.  These  f.  o.  b.  sales  carry  the 
true  characteristics  of  such  a  sale,  because  there  is  rarely  any  change  made  in  the 
f.  o.  b.  price  after  the  shipment  has  started  its  movement.  This  practice  is  some- 
what different  from  that  existing  in  Florida  where,  in  the  case  of  so-called  f.  o.  b. 
sales,  the  seller  ordinarily  guarantees  the  purchaser  against  a  decline  in  price  dur- 
ing the  time  the  shipment  is  in  transit.     *     *     * 

In  North  Carolina-Norfolk,  Va.:  The  method  of  disposition  by  growers  in  this 
area  differs  radically  from  the  customarj^  procedure  in  P'lorida  and  South  Carolina. 
In  the  latter  areas  the  local  dealers  through  whom  the  crop  is  marketed  rarely 
purchase  potatoes  outright,  but  handle  them  for  the  account  of  the  growers, 
whereas  in  the  area  now  under  consideration  a  substantial  part  of  the  crop  is 
purchased  from  growers  by  local  dealers.     *     *     * 

*  *  *  That  part  of  the  crop  not  sold  outright  to  local  dealers  and  shippers, 
consisting  in  large  part  of  potatoes  not  equal  to  U.  S.  No.  1  in  grade,  is  generally 
handled  by  the  local  shipper  on  consignment  for  the  grower's  account.  *  *  * 
The  proceeds  of  sale,  less  this  ch.qrge  and  freight  and  terminal  handling  charges, 
are  remitted  to  the  grower  or  applied  on  the  grower's  account  where  funds  had 
been  advanced  to  him.     *     *     * 

In  western  New  York:  In  western  New  York  growers  finance  their  own  opera- 
tions with  the  exception  of  some  loans  secured  through  production  credit  associa- 
tions, which  place  no  restriction  upon  disposition  of  the  crop.     *     *     * 

The  prices  paid  to  growers  in  this  area  by  buyer-loaders  and  local  dealers  are 
based  upon  carlot  prices  in  the  terminal  markets  ordinarily  supplied  from  this 
area.  The  terminal  market  delivered  price  is  reduced  by  the  freight  charge,  8 
cents  per  hundred  pounds  for  the  cost  of  the  sack,  4  cents  per  sack  to  cover  foreign 
brokerage,  and  from  15  to  20  cents  per  sack  to  cover  other  expenses  and  afford  a 
profit  to  the  dealer. 

In  Wisconsin  and  Michigan:  *  *  *  The  price  paid  to  growers  in  Wisconsin 
is  based  upon  the  Chicago  delivered  price  less  deduction's  to  cover  freight,  foreign 
brokerage,  cost  of  containers,  and  the  gross  margin  of  the  dealer  or  market  receiver. 
*  *  *  In  Michigan  the  Chicago  quotations  are  not  the  major  factor  influencing 
the  price  received  by  the  grower,  since  quotations  to  growers  in  Michigan  are 
generally  computed  on  an  f.  o.  b.  Cadillac  basis.  The  Cadillac  price  is  directly 
■dependent  upon  quotations  in  the  terminal  market  for  which  a  particular  ship- 
ment is  destined. 

DISPOSITION  BY  LOCAL  DEALERS 

In  every  commercial  producing  area  in  which  inquiry  was  made  the  majority 
of  all  shipments  destined  for  terminal  markets  is  handled  by  local  dealer-shippers 
or  other  types  of  local  marketing  organizations.  *  *  *  The  methods  of  sale 
by  local  dealers  are  quite  varied.  The  customary  methods  are:  (1)  Sales  f.  o.  b. 
shipping  point;  (2)  Delivered  sales;  (3)  Sales  through  brokers;  and  (4)  Consign- 
ment sales. 

Sales  f.  o.  b.  shipping  point  are  transactions  in  which  a  local  shipper  sells  potatoes 
loaded  in  cars  at  shipping  point.  Delivered  sales  are  those  in  which  the  shipper 
seUs  potatoes  delivered  at  a  point  designated  by  the  purchaser.  In  sales  through 
brokers  either  f.  o.  b.  or  delivered  it  is  customary  for  the  broker  to  obtain  the 
shipper's  approval  of  the  price  before  closing  the  sale.  In  these  sales  payment  is 
a  matter  between  the  shipper  and  the  purchaser  and  with  respect  to  which  no 
responsibility  attaches  to  the  broker.  A  consignment  sale  is  one  in  which  potatoes 
are  shipped  to  a  terminal  market  commission  agent  for  sale  at  the  best  price  obtain- 
able without  prior  approval  of  the  price  by  the  shipper  and  navment  is  guaranteed 
by  the  commission  agent. 


292  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

There  are  almost  infinite  variations  of  these  methods  of  selling  resulting  from 
individual  agreements  between  buyers  and  sellers.  For  instance,  the  Atlantic 
Commission  Co.  not  infrequently  handles  potatoes  on  the  basis  of  "price  arrival." 
This  term  designates  a  shipment  intended  for  the  Great  Atlantic  &  Pacific  Tea  Co., 
and  as  to  which  the  Atlantic  Commission  Co.  agrees  that  it  will  accept  the  pota- 
toes at  the  average  market  price  in  the  destination  market  on  the  day  of  arrival 
provided  the  shipment  is  in  suitable  condition.  Unless  otherwise  specified,  the 
price  is  submitted  to  the  shipper  for  confirmation  before  the  sale  is  completed. 
The  Atlantic  Commission  Co.  also  uses  "arrival  sales."  These  are  shipments 
on  which  the  best  offers  obtainable  on  a  carlot  basis  are  submitted  to  the  shipper 
for  confirmation.  The  potatoes  may  be  sold  to  the  general  trade  or  bought  by 
the  Atlantic  Commission  Co.  On  such  shipments  there  is  no  liability  on  the 
part  of  the  Atlantic  Commission  Co.  to  accept  the  potatoes,  as  is  the  case  in  "price 
arrival"  sales. 

In  f.  o.  b.  sales  the  shipper  is  paid  a  price  agreed  upon  at  the  time  sale  is  made, 
regardless  of  price  fluctuations  between  the  time  of  sale  and  the  time  of  arrival 
at  destination.  In  the  case  of  f.  o.  b.  shipments  from  Florida  and  some  other 
southern  areas  it  is  not  unusual  for  the  shipper  to  guarantee  the  price  on  arrival 
at  destination;  that  is,  if  any  decline  occurs  in  the  shipping-point  price  before  a 
shipment  reaches  its  destination  the  price  on  such  shipment  will  be  reduced 
accordingly. 

Shipments  from  southern  areas  are  customarily  sold  on  an  f.  o.  b.  basis,  unless 
the  withdrawal  of  large  buyers  from  the  f.  o.  b.  market  forces  a  resort  to  consign- 
ment sales  or  urgent  competition  from  other  early-crop  areas  makes  it  appear 
advisable  for  buyers  to  concentrate  their  purchases  in  terminal  markets.  The 
principal  exception  to  this  custom  of  selling  f.  o.  b.  results  from  advances  made 
by  market  receivers  to  local  dealers.  These  advances  are  made  by  commission 
merchants  in  terminal  markets  primarily  to  assure  themselves  of  a  supply  of  early 
potatoes  in  order  to  meet  the  requirements  of  their  trade.  This  practice  results 
in  shipments  going  to  a  specific  market  regardless  of  the.  fact  that  prices  may  be 
more  favorable  in  some  other  terminal.     *     *     * 

Dealers  in  Maine  sell  principally  upon  a  delivered  basis.  This  places  the  respon- 
sibility for  the  condition  of  the  shipment  at  destination  upon  the  shipper.  The 
risk  of  loss  from  damage  in  transit  is  an  important  factor  in  shipments  from 
Northern  points  during  winter  months. 

*  *  *  In  Wisconsin  and  Michigan  production  areas  some  terminal  market 
receivers  maintain  what  might  be  called  chain-buying  agencies.  *  *  *  Here, 
as  in  Maine,  the  delivered  sale  is  the  most  usual  type  of  transaction  between 
shipping-point  dealers  and  terminal  buyers.  The  proportion  of  potatoes  from 
these  areas  which  will  grade  U.  S.  No.  1  or  better  is  smaller  than  in  the  early 
producing  areas  or  in  Maine.  This  res"ults  in  few  sales  being  made  upon  grade, 
and  in  resort  to  sales  on  a  price  basis  subject  to  inspection  and  approval  upon 
arrival.  ' 

Fresh  fruits  and  vegetables. — Marketing  practices  for  fresh  fruits 
and  vegetables  are  also  described  at  length  by  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission  in  its  ^^ricw^^wre  Income  Inquiry,  1937.^  In  some  cases 
growers  dispose  of  their  crops  as  they  stand,  in  others  they  may  gather 
them  and  deliver  them  to  local  dealers,  in  still  others  they  retain  title 
to  them  and  ship  them  on  consignment  to  terminal  markets.  In 
general,  the  net  return  on  shipments  to  any  particular  market  will 
vary  with  day-to-day  changes  in  conditions  at  that  market.  In  the 
case  of  fruits,  prices  at  terminal  markets  are  largely  determined  by  the 
fruit  auction  system.  In  consequence  the  pattern  of  geographic  price 
variation  for  fresh  fruits  and  vegetables  is  in  no  sense  systematic. 

Cottonseed. — Cottonseed  is  usually  classed  as  an  agricultural  product 
although  its  production  does  involve  a  simple  stage  of  processing. 
The  geographic  price  structure  for  cottonseed  is  nmch  more  regular 
and  apparently  subject  to  a  substantially  greater  degree  of  control 
than  is  true  for  the  farm  products  described  above. 

'  Federal  Trade  Commission,  Agricultural  Income  Inquiry,  1937,  pt.  I,  pp.  573-581. 
8  Op.  cit. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER  293 

Prior  to  1934,  the  geographic  price  structure  for  cottonseed  was  very 
clearly  defined.  The  producing  territory — the  Cotton  Belt — was 
divided  into  a  number  of  zones  whose  boundaries  corresponded  with 
the  jurisdictions  of  the  millers'  trade  associations.  Within  each  of 
these  zones  the  mills  published  the  prices  which  they  were  willing  to 
pay  for  cottonseed  f.  o.  b.  shipping  point.  If  a  mill  in  one  zone  pur- 
chased cottonseed  from  a  gin  located  in  another  zone,  it  would  pay 
the  published  f.  o.  b.  price  in  that  zone  whether  this  price  was  higher 
or  lower  than  that  prevailing  in  its  home  zone. 

The  fact  that  shipping  point  prices,  rather  than  delivered  prices, 
are  uniform  in  each  zone  presumably  reflects  the  competitive  structure 
of  the  industry.  The  buyers  of  cottonseed — the  cottonseed  oil  mills — 
are  in  general  larger  and  more  concentrated  than  are  the  sellers  and 
are  therefore  in  a  position  to  exert  a  substantial  influence  over  the 
prices  which  they  pay  for  their  raw  material.  The  maintenance  of 
price  uniformity  at  the  shipping  point  means  that  each  mill  is  bidding 
the  same  price  for  supplies  at  every  point  and  that  there  is  no  incentive 
for  the  seller  to  deal  with  one  mill  rather  than  with  another.  This 
may  lessen  the  likelihood  of  prices  being  bid  up  by  competition  among 
buyers. 

In  a  sense,  this  form  of  price  equalization  at  the  buying  point  is  the 
obverse  of  the  more  commion  form  of  equalization  at  the  selling  point, 
but  it  springs  from  the  same  general  motivation.  Where  rival  sellers 
are  well  organized,  the  geographic  price  structure  often  reflects  the 
desire  to  avoid  price  competition  in  selling,  while  where  buyers  are  in 
a  position  to  exercise  substantial  control  over  the  market,  they  may 
wish  to  avoid  price  competition  among  themselves  in  their  purchases 
of  raw  materials. 

On  May  31,  1934,  a  Federal  Trade  Commission  complaint^  was 
issued,  as  a  result  of  which  mills  stopped  publishing  bid  prices.  At 
the  present  time  the  Department  of  Agriculture  publishes  a  range  of 
carlot  prices  on  10-ton  lots  or  more  in  those  States  where  sales  are 
based  on  a  standard  grading  system.  There  is  no  information  avail- 
able as  to  current  practices  in  the  industry.  However,  according  to  a 
recent  study,  there  is  some  evidence  that  the  exchange  of  price  infor- 
mation between  mills  continues. '° 

FOOD    AND    KINDRED    PRODUCTS 

In  terms  of  value  of  products,  the  group  of  industries  classed  by  the 
Census  Bureau  as  Food  and  Kindred  Products  is  much  the  largest 
group  in  the  American  economy.  Total  value  of  product  during  1935 
was  ahnost  $10,000,000,000." 

The  geographic  price  structures  of  food  products  reflect  a  very  wide 
diversity  in  market  characteristics  such  as  perishabihty,  degree  of  pro- 
cessing, extent  of  standardization,  importance  of  trade-marks  and  brand 
names,  relative  importance  of  freight  as  an  item  in  cost,  etc.  Accord- 
ingly they  exhibit  almost  every  recognized  pattern  of  variation  in- 
cluding basing-point  systems,  zone  systems,  f.  o.  b.  plant  pricing, 
freight  equalization,  and  uniform  delivered  prices,  as  well  as  com- 
pletely unsystematic  price  variation  between  markets.     In  general, 

»  Federal  Trade  Commission  Docket  No.  2190. 

'« Walton  Hamilton  and  Associates,  Prices  and  Price  Policies,  p.  281. 

"  Bureau  of  Census,  Biennial  Census  of  Manufactures,  1935,  p.  42. 


294  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC,  POWER 

there  is  some  relationship  between  the  degree  of  processing  and  the 
character  of  the  geographic  price  structure;  slightly  processed  com- 
modities, such  as  meats,  tend  to  vary  in  as  irregular  a  fashion  as 
agricultural  products,  while  foods  which  have  undergone  a  greater 
degree  of  fabrication  and  particularly  those  which  are  branded  or 
trade-marked  commonly  display  the  more  conventional  types  of 
structure  usually  associated  with  the  products  of  industry.  There 
are  often  differences  in  the  geographic  price  structure  for  a  single 
product,  depending  upon  whether  it  is  sold  under  a  national  brand, 
under  a  distributor's  brand,  or  in  bulk;  advertised  brands  are  more 
commonly  sold  on  a  delivered  or  freight  allowed  basis  than  are  private 
brands  or  bulk  products. 

Because  of  the  diversity  of  products  included  in  the  food  industry, 
it  would  be  impractical  to  discuss  in  detail  the  geographic  price  struc- 
ture prevailing  for  even  a  reasonably  representative  selection  of  items. 
Instead  a  very  limited  list  of  commodities  has  been  accorded  separate 
treatment,  followed  by  a  tabular  summary  of  the  prevailing  geographic 
price  structures  for  a  considerably  wider  group. 

Meats. — The  price  of  meat  products  in  different  cities  of  the  United 
States  seems  to  bear  no  apparent  relationship  to  their  cost  of  shipment 
from  major  producing  centers  or  from  central  markets.  This  is  clearly 
illustrated  in  the  case  of  beef  by  the  report  of  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission  in  its  Agricultm'al  Income  Inquiry. ^^  This  report  lists 
the  average  wholesale  prices  for  "good  beef  carcass"  in  51  cities,  during 
the  year  November  1934  to  October  1935.'^  The  weighted  average 
price  per  100  pounds  for  all  51  cities  was  $16.28.  Prices  in  the  two 
large  packing  centers — Chicago  and  Kansas  City — were  $17.22  and 
$18.02  respectively,  or  materially  above  this  average  for  the  United 
States.  In  contrast,  the  value  in  Baltimore,  which  is  remote  from 
the  major  producing  area,  was  only  $14.41,  while  in  Washington  it 
was  $15.91  and  in  New  York,  $16.43.  Prices  ranged  from  a  low  of 
$11.89  in  Portland,  Oreg.,  to  a  high  of  $19.12  in  New  Haven,  Conn., 
but  there  was  no  evidence  of  any  variation  which  might  be  considered 
to  reflect  the  location  of  supply  in  relation  to  markets. 

The  range  of  veal  prices  is  even  greater  than  that  for  beef.  Accord- 
ing to  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  report,'^  average  wholesale  prices 
per  100  pounds  for  the  period  November  1934  to  October  1935,  varied 
from  $8.88  in  Little  Rock,  Ark.,  to  $17.93  in  Washington,  D.  C.  The 
weighted  average  for  all  51  cities  was  $14.75  and  prices  in  terminal 
markets  at  Kansas  City  and  Chicago  were  $12.36  and  $14.75  per  100 
pounds  respectively.  Again  the  variation  did  not  reveal  any  con- 
sistent pattern  in  which  the  influence  of  transportation  charges  to 
and  from  terminal  markets  could  be  clearly  traced. 

Vegetable  oils. — There  are  three  zones  observed  in  the  sale  of  cotton- 
seed oil:  the  southeastern  area,  which  includes  aU  southeastern  States 
as  far  west  as  Alabama  and  eastern  Tennessee  inclusive,  the  Mississippi 
Valley  area  including  Louisiana,  Arkansas,  and  western  Tennessee,  and 
the  southwestern  area  including  Texas  and  Oklahoma.  In  each  of 
these  areas  prices  are  quoted  f.  o.  b.  mill,  with  the  prices  for  all  mills  in 
any  given  zone  the  same  at  any  time.  The  price  is  usually  lowest  lq 
the  southwest,  %  cent  higher  in  the  Mississippi  Valley,  and  again 

"  Federal  Trade  Commission,  Agricultural  Income  Inauiry,  pt.  I  .Principa  IFarm  Products,  1937. 
"  Ibid,  pp.  158-159. 
"  Ibid,  pp.  169,  170. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  295 

higher  by  about  another  }i  cent  in  the  Southeast.  Cottonseed  oil  is 
traded  on  organized  exchanges  which  largely  influence  the  prevailing 
price.  It  is  understood  that  the  boundaries  of  the  zones  are  related 
to  the  railroad  freight-rate  structure  and  that  purchasers  of  cottonseed 
oil  are  usually  unable  to  cross  from  one  zone  to  another  in  their  buying 
because  this  would  involve  their  losing  the  advantage  of  the  most  fa- 
vorable "fabrication-in-transit"  rates. 

The  prices  of  soybean  and  other  minor  vegetable  oils  are  said  to  be 
usually  uniform  in  crushers'  mills  over  the  entire  country. 

Vegetable  shortening. — Nationally  advertised  vegetable  shortening  is 
sold  on  a  delivered  basis  at  uniform  prices  anywhere  in  the  United 
States.  However,  in  the  case  of  at  least  one  well-known  brand, 
there  are  special  prices  in  effect  in  some  of  the  Southern  States,  in 
the  Mountain  States,  and  in  the  western  section  of  the  Dakotas, 
Nebraska,  and  Kansas.  The  lower  prices  in  effect  in  these  zones  are 
for  the  purpose  of  introducing  the  sale  of  this  product  in  those  areas 
and  suggest  another  of  the  considerations  which  may  afi'ect  geographic 
price  structures. 

Unadvertised  or  private  brajids  as  well  as  bulk  shortening  are  sold 
f.  o.  b.  shipping  point  with  no  freight  allowed. 

Bread. — The  market  for  bread  is  largely  local  in  that  the  product 
is  rarely  shipped  any  considerable  distance  from  the  bakery.  Prices 
to  distributors  are  on  a  delivered  basis  and  are  uniform  for  the  same 
kind  of  customer  within  any  given  locality.  However,  the  same 
bakery  may  sell  at  quite  different  prices  in  adjacent  areas  and  it  is 
not  uncommon  for  the  price  to  be  lower  in  a  town  at  some  distance 
from  the  plant  than  at  nearer  points.  For  example,  according  to  the 
Department  of  Agriculture,  the  Washington,  D.  C,  plant  of  a  large 
baking  company  sells  bread  in  Washington  at  a  wholesale  price  of  16 
ounces  for  8  cents,  equivalent  to  8  cents  per  poimd,  while  the  same 
plant  sells  to  Fredericksburg,  Va.,  at  a  price  of  22  ounces  for  8  cents, 
equivalent  to  5.8  cents  per  pound.  The  same  company  operating 
from  another  plant  sells  its  bread  at  8  cents  per  pound  in  Norfolk, 
Va.,  and  at  6.4  cents  per  pound  across  the  river  in  Newport  News.^^ 
This  sort  of  price  variation  is  clearly  not  related  in  any  way  to  trans- 
portation costs.  In  fact  there  is  some  evidence  that  the  effect  of 
this  kind  of  geographic  pricing  practice  on  the  part  of  this  large  com- 
pany may  be  to  create  difficulties  for  smaller  competitors  located  in 
the  areas  in  which  prices  are  arbitrarily  reduced. ^^ 

Sugar. — The  prices  of  refined  sugar  at  any  point  in  the  United 
States  are  related  to  the  prices  of  cane  sugar  at  seaport  refineries  on 
the  Atlantic,  Gulf,  and  Pacific  coasts.  These  ports  in  effect  consti- 
tute multiple  basing  points  and  the  base  prices  at  each  such  point  are 
usually  identical.  This  structure  reflects  the  fact  that  practically  all 
cane  sugar  refining,  which  accounts  for  approximately  80  percent  of 
all  refined  sugar  produced  in  the  United  States,  is  conducted  at  these 
seaboard  refineries.  The  uniformity  of  prices  at  all  basing  points 
may  be  explained  by  the  fact  that  the  bulk  of  raw  sugar  consumed 
in  the  United  States  is  imported,  and  the  costs  of  shipping  this  raw 

'5  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  Press  Release,  T.  N.  E.  C.  30,  January  29,  1940. 

"  These  practices  have  been  the  subject  of  complaints  issued  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  on  the 
ground  that  they  "tend  to  create  a  monopoly."  See  F.  T.  C.  Docket  No.  3669,  dated  December  17,  1938, 
relating  to  the  practice  in  the  District  of  Columbia  and  Vireinia  areas;  and  F.  T.  C.  Docket  No.  3740,  dated 
March  20,  1939,  relating  to  the  same  subject  in  Iowa,  Minnesota,  South  Dakota,  and  Nebraska.  The 
former  case  is  still  pending;  a  Cease  and  Desist  Order  was  issued  for  the  latter  case  on  December  28,  19.39. 

247149—41 — No.  1 21 


296  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

sugar  from  its  points  of  production  to  any  of  these  seaports  will  not 
vary  significantly.  The  delivered  price  of  cane  sugar  at  any  destina- 
tion is  arrived  at,  theoretically,  on  this  basis  of  "seaboard  plus";  in 
other  words  it  is  computed  by  adding  the  cost  of  combined  rail- 
water-truck  shipment  to  the  base  price.  Some  years  ago  it  was  the 
custom  to  compute  freight  on  an  all-rail  basis  only,  but  the  increas- 
ing use  of  water  and  truck  transportation  forced  a  modification  of 
the  practice. 

Beet  sugar,  which  is  produced  primarily  at  inland  points  in  the 
West,  is  directly  competitive  with  cane  sugar  and  consequently  shows 
the  same  general  pattern  of  geographic  variation.  However,  there 
appears  to  be  a  slight  difference  in  popular  acceptance  which  results 
in  a  r'elatively  minor  price  dift'erential  between  cane  and  beet  sugars. 
Under  ordinary  circumstances  tne  price  of  beet  sugar  in  any  market 
is  20  points — i.  e.,  $0.20  per  100  pounds — below  that  of  cane  sugar 
in  the  same  market.  The  result  of  this  practice  is  that  the  highest 
price  for  beet  sugar  occurs  around  Pittsburgh  beyond  which  point  it 
becomes  unprofitable  to  ship  it  and  which  represents  its  longest  haul, 
while  its  lowest  price  is  in  the  region  adjacent  to  its  producing 
centers. 

In  basing  point  cities,  the  delivered  price  usually  includes  a  small 
charge  for  trucking  which  is  in  some  respects  similar  to  the  switching 
charges  observed  at  steel  basing  points.  For  example,  in  New  York 
City  during  April  1939  there  was  a  charge  of  three  points  for  truck 
deliveries  involving  stops  at  more  than  one  store. 

An  indication  of  the  approximate  relative  importance  of  freight,  on 
shipments  of  various  length,  is  afforded  by  the  following  schedule  of 
freight  extras  prevailing  during  April  1939,  at  a  time  when  the  base 
price  approximated  $.044  per  pound. 

Freight  extras  pi  r 
100  pounds 

Bridpeport,  Conn ^ $0.  14 

Pittsburgh,  Pa 0.  28 

Cleveland.  Ohio 0.  36 

Springfield,  111 0.  42/2 

Minneapolis,  Minn 0.  54 

As  in  the  case  of  many  other  commodities,  adherence  to  the  struc- 
ture just  described  is  by  no  means  perfect.  The  nominal  quotations 
are  often  shaded  to  meet  competitive  conditions.  In  addition  the 
differential  between  beet  sugar  and  cane  sugar  may  vary  from  time 
to  time,  although  it  usually  remains  within  the  range  between  10 
and  20  points.  Guarantees  against  price  decline  are  common,  and 
concessions  of  this  sort  affect  not  only  current  transactions  but  also 
past  orders  within  the  terms  of  the  guarantee.  Since  price  conces- 
sions of  this  kind  do  not  affect  all  markets  uniformly,  they  amount  to 
modifications  of  the  nominal  geographic  price  structure. 

Salt. — Salt  is  marketed  in  accordance  with  a  complex  freight  equali- 
zation system  which  operates  on  a  zone  basis.  The  delivered  price 
at  any  point  in  a  zone  is,  in  general,  determined  by  adding  freight 
costs  to  the  f.  o.  b.  price  of  the  most  advantageously  located  plant  in 
that  zone.  Sellers  located  outside  the  zone  play  no  part  in  price- 
making  beyond  the  limits  of  their  accepted  territory. 

Salt  is  produced  commercially  in  only  12  States.  Of  these  two,  New 
Mexico  and  Nevada,  produce  very  little  salt  and  a  third,  Oklahoma, 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         297 

has  not  until  recently  been  sufficiently  important  to  warrant  being 
considered  a  separate  producing-  field.  The  eight  producing  fields 
recognized  by  the  industry  are  New  York,  Ohio,  and  West  Virginia, 
Michigan,  Louisiana,  Texas,  Kansas  and  Oldahoma,  Utah,  and 
California.  "Natural  marketing  areas"  have  been  established  roughly 
corresponding  to  these  producing  regions  and  producers  generally 
refrain  from  selling  in  a  marketing  area,  other  than  their  own,  at  a 
price  lower  than  that  of  producers  in  the  field.  Within  each  area  a 
system  of  freight  equalization  prevails  and  "freight  books"  are  used 
to  insure  uniformity  of  delivered  prices.  Producers  outside  the  area 
may  compete  at  the  same  prices  but  they  often  set  a  limit  to  the  amount 
of  freight  which  they  are  willing  to  absorb  in  order  to  do  so. 

The  functioning  of  the  system  is  well  described  in  a  report  prepared 
by  the  Division  of  Review  of  the  National  Recovery  Administration. 
According  to  the  best  information  available,  the  same  general  structure 
still  prevails. 

Following  the  organization  of  the  Salt  Producers'  Association  in  1914,  that 
organization  prepared  and  published  what  were  known  as  State  freight  rate  books 
for  every  State  in  the  Union.  These  freight  rate  books  contained  the  name  of 
every  known  delivery  point,  or  point  of  destination,  in  each  State,  together  with, 
the  railroad  freight  rate  to  such  delivery  point  from  the  nearest  producing  plant, 
The  various  producers,  in  calculating  the  delivered  price  of  salt  to  such  point  of 
destination,  would  add  to  the  base  price  the  figure  set  forth  in  the  State  freight 
rate  book.  Thus,  every  producing  plant  became  a  basing  point  for  all  delivery 
points  nearer  to  it  than  to  any  other  plant. 

The  following  quotation  is  an  excerpt  from  a  letter,  written  by  a  member  of  the 
industry  to  a  Nebraska  wholesale  grocer  in  1915,  explaining  the  method  of  using 
price  lists  and  freight  rate  books  (which  system  is  still  in  effect): 

"We  have  sent  to  you  Nebraska  and  Iowa  books  and  scales.  You  will  note  that 
there  are  two  scales — one  scale  No.  7,  which  applies  on  Michigan  salt,  the  other 
scale  No.  Z-7,  which  applies  on  Kansas  salt.  The  rate  books  show  freight  rates 
both  from  Michigan  and  Kansas.  The  method  of  using  the  books  is  very  simple. 
Take  the  town  of  Weeping  Willow,  Nebr.,  for  example.  Reference  to  the  rate 
book  will  show  that  the  cheapest  rate  to  Weeping  Willow  is  from  Kansas,  and  is 
36  cents.  To  arrive  at  the  price  to  Weeping  Willow,  use  the  Z-7  book  and  look 
under  column  36,  which  will  show  that  the  price  of  Number  1  Jack  Rabbit  is  $1.21. 
This  is  the  price  to  be  charged  a  retail  dealer.  From  this  price  you  are  allowed  a 
5-cent  per  barrel  commission,  as  shown  on  the  last  page  of  the  schedule.  We 
insist  that  the  wholesale  grocer  keep  the  discount  for  themselves  and  shall  not  in 
any  way  rebate  to  the  customer  or  sell  him  at  prices  less  than  those  shown  in  our 
schedule. 

"To  arrive  at  the  price  on  Michigan  Salt  to  Weeping  Willow,  we  refer  to  the 
Michigan  rate,  which  is  57  cents.  Recently,  however,  it  has  become  the  practice 
of  Michigan  manufacturers  to  absorb  the  difference  befiween  Michigan  and  Kansas 
rates  to  the  extent  of  15  cents  per  barrel.  Therefore,  the  Michigan  price  to  Weep- 
ing Willow  would  be  at  the  rate  of  57  cents  less  the  maximum  absorption  of  15 
cents,  which  makes  42  cents,  and  the  price  of  salt  from  Michigan  to  Weeping 
Willow  is  found  in  Column  42  of  the  Michigan  Schedule.  Thus,  the  price  on 
Michigan  salt  is  $1.27  per  barrel." 

The  amount  of  freight  absorption  varied  considerably,  depending  on  the  need 
for  an  expanded  market  on  the  part  of  manufacturers  in  any  given  area,  and  even 
varied  on  different  grades  of  salt.  Thus,  in  1932,  we  find  one  southern  manu- 
facturer issuing  a  price  schedule  containing  instructions  to  salesmen  to  limit 
freight  absorption  on  rock  salt  in  Southern  States  to  a  point  which  would  net  the 
producer  at  least  $4  per  ton  at  the  plant,  but  permitting  complete  freight  absorp- 
tion to  all  points  of  destination  on  high-grade  industrial  salt.  In  sales  in  Ken- 
tucky, for  example,  the  salesman  is  instructed  to  figure  freight  rates  on  the 
Michigan  or  Ohio  freight  rate,  whichever  is  lower,  instead  of  figuring  the  freight 
rate  on  the  actual  cost  from  I.ouisiana,  except  that  on  rock  salt  the  absorption  of 
freight  was  limited  to  a  figure  which  would  net  the  producer  $4  per  ton.*^ 

"National  Recovery  Administration,  Division  of  Review — Manufacturers  Control  of  Distribution:  A 
Study  of  Trade  Practice  Provisions  in  Selected  National  Recovery  Administration  Codes,  by  Irwin  S. 
Moise  and  George  B.  Haddock;  Work  Materials  No.  62,  March  J 930.  pp.  82,  83. 


298  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  maintenance  of  this  elaborate  system  may  be  explained  partly 
by  the  relative  standardization  of  the  product  ^^  and  partly  by  the 
great  importance  of  freight  as  an  element  in  the  delivered  price  of 
salt.  According  to  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission/®  rail 
freight  revenue  on  carload  shipments  of  salt  amounted  to  46  percent 
of  the  delivered  value  of  the  product  at  destination  during  1936. 
During  1933,  when  prices  were  lower,  Interstate  Commerce  Com- 
mission data  show  that  freight  reached  the  high  ratio  of  64  percent 
of  delivered  value;  in  other  words,  almost  two-thirds  of  the  average 
delivered  wholesale  price  of  salt  represented  the  cost  of  transporta- 
tion.2» 

The  two  largest  producers,  who  are  apparently  the  price  leaders  of 
the  industry,  have  plants  in  many  different  producing  areas  and 
between  them  they  are  direct  market  factors  in  44  of  the  48  States.^' 
Consequently  there  is  little  incentive  for  these  two  concerns  to  dump 
their  surplus  product  across  zone  boundaries.  At  the  same  time  they 
are  in  a  position  to  utilize  their  prestige  for  the  purpose  of  maintain- 
ing the  established  system,  and  according  to  the  National  Recovery 
Administration  report  quoted: 

There  is  some  evidence  to  the  effect  that  this  uniformity  in  published  prices 
resulted  from  a  definite  fear  on  the  part  of  smaller  producers  of  disastrous  re- 
prisals if  they  disturbed  the  prices  established  by  the  larger,  more  powerful 
producers.22 

Nevertheless  the  system  is  not  always  rigidly  observed  and  there  is 
considerable  evidence  of  price  cutting  during  periods  of  stress.  It  is 
possible  that  the  tendency  on  the  part  of  smaller  producers  to  cut 
prices  occasionally  is  related  to  their  difficulty  in  competing  on  the 
basis  of  uniform  prices  with  larger  companies  who  have  obtained 
public  acceptance  for  their  advertised  brands.^^  Sometimes  sporadic 
price  cutting  culminates  in  severe  price  wars  during  which  the  entire 
geographic  structure  may  become  little  more  than  nominal.  Such  a 
price  war  occurred,  for  example,  during  the  latter  part  of  the  National 
Recoveiy  Administration  period  in  1935: 

Following  May  27,  1935,  deviations  from  published  prices  became  more  and 
more  troublesome.  By  August,  the  secret  prices  evidently  became  sufficiently 
serious  to  warrant  retaliation  by  the  price  leaders  in  the  industry.  Since  that 
time,  there  has  developed  one  of  the  worst  price  wars  experienced  in  recent  years 
by  this  industry.  Published  prices  remain  practically  the  same  as  they  were 
during  the  code  period,  but  discounts  and  rebates  ranging  from  20  to  30  percent 
are  being  granted  to  various  types  of  buyers.^* 

Coffee. — Unadvertised  b^'ands  of  coffee  are  generally  sold  f.  o.  b. 
shipping  point  with  no  freight  allowance.  Nationally  advertised 
brands,  on  the  other  hand,  are  often  sold  on  a  uniform  delivered  price 
basis.  Thus  one  company  charges  a  uniform  price  for  store  door 
delivery  anywhere  in  the  United  States,  another  prepays  freight  to 
the  buyer's  city  only,  and  a  third  prepays  freight  to  the  buyer's  city 
but  quotes  different  prices  east  and  west  of  the  Rocky  Mountains. 

Rice. — Rice  in  bulk,  as  well  as  unadvertised  or  private  brands,  is 
sold  on  a  simple  f.  o.  b.  shipping-point  basis  with  no  freight  allowed. 

"  Trade  names  and  brands  have  some  effect  upon  this  marnet,  but  not  enough  to  support  an  appreciable 
price  differential. 
>•  Op.  eit. 

M  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  Freight  Revenue  and  Value  of  Commodities  Transported,  1933. 
"  Manufacturers  Control  of  Distribution,  p.  81. 
a  Ibid.,  p.  83. 
M  Ibid.,  p.  145. 
«  Ibid.,  p.  147. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  299 

In  the.  case  of  nationally  advertised  brands,  practices  vary.  One 
brand  is  sold  at  a  uniform  delivered  price  at  all  eastern  seaports  and 
a  uniform  differential  above  this  at  all  other  points.  Another  brand 
is  sold  full  freight  allowed,  except  in  a  group  of  midwestern  and 
mountain  States  in  which  the  delivered  price  is  higher. 

Other  food  products. — Prevailing  geographic  price  structures  for 
othor  food  products  are  summarized  below.  Where  the  practice 
applies  only  under  certain  conditions,  e.  g.,  to  manufacturers  brands, 
unadvertised  brands,  or  in  bulk,  the  limitation  is  noted.  When 
there  is  no  such  note  the  practice  applies  generally  regardless  of 
brand  or  packaging. 

The  following  products  are  usually  sold  f.  o.  b.  shipping  point  with 
no  freight  allowed: 

Grape  juice:  Nationally  advertised  brands  and  bulli  only. 

Corn  meal:  Unadvertised  brands  and  bulk  only. 

Crackers:  Unadvertised  brands  only. 

Wheat  flour. 

Chocolate  coating:  Unadvertised  brands  and  bulk. 

Cocoa:  Bulk  only. 

Creamery  butter:  Bulk  purchases  in  certain  cases  only. 

Condensed  milk:  Bulk  purchases  in  certain  cases  only. 

Processed  cheese:  Unadvertised  brands  only. 

Bulk  cheese. 

Canned  peaches. 

Canned  pineapple. 

Dried  apricots. 

Prunes. 

Raisins. 

Canned  soup:  Unadvertised  brands  only. 

Canned  corn:  Unadvertised  and  some  advertised  brands. 

Canned  peas:  Unadvertised  and  some  advertised  brands. 

Canned  tomatoes. 

Vegetable  shortening:  Unadvertised  brands  and  bulk  only. 

Lard. 

Molasses:  Bulk  purchases  in  certain  cases  only. 

Black  pepper:  F.  o.  b.  warehouse,  New  York  City  or  port  of  arrival. 

Canned  salmon:  Advertised  and  unadvertised  brands. 

Tea:  Bulk. 

Vinegar:  Bulk. 

The  following  products  are  sold  either  at  uniform  delivered  prices 
anywhere  in  the  United  States  or  f.  o.  b.  shipping  point,  full  freight 
allowed.     The  latter  practice  is  indicated  by  the  initials  "f.  a." 

Ginger  ale  and  club  soda:  Advertised  brands,  f.  a.  (except  in  Washington  and 
Oregon  where  freight  allowance  is  limited  to  50  cents  per  100  pounds). 

Ginger  ale  and  club  soda:  Unadvertised  or  private  brands. 

Grape  juice:  Advertised  brands  (f.  a.  to  warehouse  city). 

Corn  flakes:  Advertised  brands  (some  quoted  f.  a.,  others  delivered). 

Wheat  cereal:  Advertised  brands,  f.  a. 

Crackers:  Advertised  brands,  f.  a. 

Macaroni:  F.  a  (on  unadvertised  brands  freight  allowance  may  be  for  carlots 
only). 

Pretzels:  Nationally  advertised  and  bulk,  f.  a. 

Packaged  candy:  Nationally  advertised,  f.  a. 

Cocoa:  Nationally  advertised,  f.  a. 

Creamery  butter:  Bulk  delivered  in  some  cases. 

Condensed  milk. 

Powdered  milk:  Nationally  advertised. 

Toilet  soap,  bar  laundry  soap,  and  soap  flakes:  Private  brands  or  bulk,  f.  a., 
nationally  advertised  brands  delivered. 

Canned  soup:  Advertised  brands,  f.  a. 

Baked  Beans:  One  advertised  brand,  f.  a.     Unadvertised  brands,  f.  a.  in  carlots. 


300  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Canned  corn  and  canned  peas:  Some  advertised  brands. 
Canned  tomato  juice:  Advertised  brands,  f.  a. 

Jelly:  Some  advertised  brands,  f.  a.     Unadvertised  brands,  f.  a.  in  carJots. 
Molasses:  Some  advertised  brands,  f.  a.,  and  bulk  sometimes  f.  a. 
Oleomargarine. 

Peanut  butter:  Some  advertised  brands,  f.  a.,  and  unadvertised  brands,  f.  a. 
in  carlots. 

Tea:  Advertised  brands. 

Vinegar:  Some  advertised  brands  f.  a.,  and  unadvertised  brands,  f.  a.  in  carlots. 

The  following  products  are  sold  on  a  zone  basis  with  two  delivery 
zones,  east  and  west  of  the  Rocky  Mountains. 

Corn  flakes:  Unadvertised  brands. 

Farina:  Unadvertised  brands. 

Oatmeal:  Unadvertised  brands. 

Cooked  wheat  cereal:  Unadvertised  brands. 

Powdered  milk:  Bulk. 

The  following  products  are*  sold  on  a  zone  delivered  basis  with 
three  or  four  zones  recognized. 

Farina,  oatmeal  and  cornmeal:  Advertised  brands. 

Evaporated  milk. 

Processed  cheese:  Nationally  advertised. 

The  following  nationally  advertised  products  are  sold  by  at  least 
one  manufacturer  on  a  delivered -price  basis,  using  six  or  seven  zones: 
Canned  baked  beans,  jelly,  molasses,  peanut  butter,  vinegar. 

Bulk  corn  sirup  and  bulk  cornstarch  are  sold  in  accordance  with  a 
basing  point  system  on  carload  factory  shipments. 

Packaged  sirup  in  carlots  is  sold  on  a  basing  point  system  in  some 
areas  and  on  a  zone  delivered  price  basis  in  others. 

Packaged  starch  in  carlots  is  sold  on  a  delivered  basis  with  prices 
varying  in  12  or  more  zones. 

TEXTILES  AND  TEXTILE  PRODUCTS 

Transportation  constitutes  only  a  minor  item  in  the  price  of  most 
textiles  and  textile  products.  During  1936,  according  to  the  Inter- 
state Commerce  Commission,  freight  was  only  2.5  percent  of  the  value 
of  baled  cotton  at  its  destination;  for  cotton  cloth  and  cotton  fabrics 
the  ratio  of  freight  to  value  was  1.8  percent.^'  It  is  logical  to  assume 
that  the  relative  importance  of  freight  is  even  less  for  finished  apparel 
and  for  more  expensive  fibers  such  as  silk,  wool,  and  rayon. 

The  minor  rple  played  by  freight  is  probably  at  least  in  part  re- 
sponsible for  the  absence  of  any  complex  forms  of  freight  equalization 
or  zone  pricing  in  the  markets  for  these  products.  A  few  products 
are  sold  on  a  uniform  delivered  basis  but  the  general  practice  seems  to 
be  to  quote  straight  f.  o.  b.  mill  or  f.  o.  b.  mill  with  occasional  minor 
modifications. 

Yarns. — Cotton  yarns  are  sold  on  a  sim])le  f.  o.  b.  mill  system. 
Knitters  constitute  the  principal  market  for  this  product  because 
cotton  weaving  is  almost  entirely  in  the-hands  of  integrated  mills. 

Rayon  yarn  is  sold  on  a  freight-allowed    basis.     Quotations  are 
f.  o.  b.  producer's  plant  with  minimum  freight  allowed  to  destination. 
The  term  "minimum  freight"  simply  means  that  the  amount  of  freight 
allowance  is  determined  by  the  lowest  shipping  rate  available,  regard 
less  of  the  route  actually  used. 

»•  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  op.  clt. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  301 

The  geographic  structure  for  woolen  yarns  varies  with  the  type  of 
yarn.  Weavmg  yarns  are  sold  f.  o.  b.  mill.  Knitting  yams,  however, 
are  sold  on  a  delivered  basis  in  the  Philadelphia,  New  York,  Cleveland, 
and  New  England  areas;  for  other  points  they  are  sold  f.  o.  b.  shipping 
point  of  the  finished  (dyed)  yarn.  Apparently  knitting  yams  are 
usually  dyed  and  finished  by  companies  other  than  the  spinners  and 
the  practice  is  to  quote  the  price  f.  o.  b.  the  finishing  plant. 

Gray  goods. — Gray  goods — both  cotton  and  rayon — are  understood 
to  be  sold  on  a  stniiglit  f.  o.  b.  mill  basis  with  no  important  modifi- 
cations. 

Finished  cloth. — In  general,  cotton  and  wool  finished  cloth,  as  well 
as  gray  goods,  is  quoted  on  a  straight  f.  o.  b.  mill  basis.  There  are, 
however,  certain  variations.  Clothiers'  linings  and  corset  cloths  are 
usually  sold  on  a  delivered  basis  to  New  York  manufacturers,  who 
apparently  constitute  a  major  segment  of  the  market  for  these  prod- 
ucts and  are  consequently  able  to  exert  an  important  influence  upon 
their  terms  of  purchase. ^^  However,  the  price  to  manufacturers 
outside  New  York  is  f.  o.  b.  mill.  Clothiers'  linings  and  corset  cloths 
sold  to  retailers  are  quoted  either  f.  o.  b.  mill  or,  if  shipped  from 
New  York  stocks,  f.  o.  b.  New  York  warehouse. 

Finished  raj'on  cloth  is  sold  on  a  delivered  basis  to  metropolitan 
areas  where  warehouses  are  located;  in  other  areas  it  is  sold  f.  o.  b. 
mill  or  warehouse,  whichever  is  lower. 

Finished  apparel. — The  great  bulk  of  finished  apparel  is  sold  on  the 
basis  of  a  simple  f.  o,  b.  system.  This  practice  is  followed  even  though 
there  is  a  tendency  for  retail  prices  to  the  consumer  to  be  uniform 
throughout  the  United  States  either  because  of  the  existence  of  con- 
ventional price  lines  or,  in  the  case  of  some  nationally  advertised 
products,  because  of  price  maintenance  efforts  by  manufacturers. 

Under  these  circumstances  it  becomes  necessary  for  the  retailer — 
who  usually  purchases  directly  from  the  manufacturer — to  absorb  the 
cost  of  freight  in  his  gross  margin.  Although  this  might  be  thought 
to  impose  a  burden  upon  retailers  who  are  unfavorably  located  with 
reference  to  their  sources  of  supply,  the  actual  cost  of  shipment  is  very 
low  for  most  apparel  and  consequently  the  problemi  is  not  serious. 
During  recent  years,  freight  costs  have  been  further  reduced  by  the 
increasing  use  of  truck  delivery.  In  general,  therefore,  the  f.  o.  b. 
system  seems  to  be  observed  simply  because  the  element  of  freight  is 
too  minor  to  become  the  subject  of  competitive  bargaining,  especially 
in  view  of  the  emphasis  placed  by  the  market  upon  nonprice  factors 
such  as  style. 

The  prevailing  f.  o.  b.  system  is  subject  to  some  modifications,  a  few 
of  which  are  generally  recognized.  Thus  it  is  common  practice  to 
allow  free  delivery  anywhere  within  the  city  or  metropolitan  area  in 
which  the  apparel  is  manufactured.  Since  the  cost  of  such  delivery 
is  unlikely  to  be  great,  this  is  a  minor  concession. 

In  the  case  of  a  number  of  products.  New  York  City  retailers  are 
apparently  granted  a  favored  position  and  allowed  free  delivery  by 
manufacturers  located  anywhere  in  the  United  States.  This  is  often 
true,  for  example,  of  women's  dresses  and  men's  suits  and  shirts. 
The  practice  probably  reflects  the  historical  development  of  the  in- 
dustries.    It  is  only  recently  that  wornen's  dresses  and  men's  siijts 

"  The  same  practice  was  at  one  time  followed  in  connection  with  the  sale  of  shiitings  to  New  York  maba- 
facfurers,  but  it  has  since  been  abandoned. 


302  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

have  come  to  be  produced  in  any  quantity  outside  of  New  York ;  the 
production  of  men's  shirts  was  for  a  long  time  concentrated  exclusively 
in  the  Troy,  N.  Y.,  and  New  York  City  areas.  As  a  result,  metro- 
politan retailers  undoubtedly  became  accustomed  to  free  delivery. 
As  mills  were  established  in  other  areas,  it  may  have  been  natural  for 
these  retailers  to  insist  upon  their  customary  prerogatives  as  a  con- 
dition of  purchase.  Even  at  the  present  time  the  bulk  of  men's 
suits  and  women's  dresses  (except  wash  frocks)  is  produced  in  New 
York  City.  At  the  same  time  the  great  importance  of  this  market 
and  the  bargaining  power  of  the  large  department  stores  in  the  area  " 
are  probably  factors  in  maintaining  the  custom. 

Companies  which  have  showrooms  in  more  than  one  city  may  allow 
free  delivery  in  any  of  these  cities  and  base  freight  charges  to  other 
points  on  the  rates  from  the  nearest  such  free  dehvery  point. 

In  addition  to  these  generally  observed  practices,  a  few  companies 
absorb  freight  more  or  less  regularly.  For  example,  a  few  wash  frock 
manufacturers  in  California  pay  one-half  of  the  freight  charges  on 
shipments  to  the  East  in  order  to  compete  with  eastern  houses,  but 
this  seems  to  be  an  exception  rather  than  the  rule.  One  manufacturer 
of  flannelette  garments  in  Michigan  equalizes  his  freight  on  a  New  York 
basis.  A  large  work  clothing  manufacturer  allows  freight  on  ship- 
ments exceeding  a  specified  number  of  garments.  An  important 
knit  goods  producer,  who  advertises  on  a  national  scale,  sells  on  a 
delivered  basis. 

In  addition  to  practices  of  this  kind,  which  form  a  part  of  the  estab- 
lished policy  of  most  members  of  an  industry  or  of  individual  firms, 
a  very  limited  amount  of  freight  absorption  may  be  encountered  on 
specific  transactions  when  the  producer  feels  it  necessary  to  make  a 
minor  concession  in  order  to  consummate  a  sale.  In  general,  however, 
concessions  of  this  kind  are  made  in  the  form  of  an  outright  reduction 
in  the  price  quotation. 

It  should  be  emphasized  that  these  deviations  from  simple  f.  o.  b. 
pricing  which  have  been  described  are  all  exceptions  from  a  widely 
observed  general  rule. 

Binder  twine. — The  geographic  price  structure  for  hard  fibers  and 
their  products  does  not  usually  conform  with  the  pattern  for  the  textile 
products  which  have  been  described  above.  For  example,  binder 
twine  is  sold  on  the  basis  of  a  system  of  freight  equalization.  Three 
of  the  largest  producers  in  this  industry  are  definitely  known  to  observe 
this  practice  and  presumably  smaller  producers  follow  their  lead  in 
this  respect. 

However,  an  appreciable  proportion  of  binder  twine  is  produced  in 
prison  shops  and.  it  is  doubtful  that  these  observe  the  same  selling 
practices.  In  the  case  of  the  Minnesota  and  Wisconsin  State  prisons, 
prices  are  apparently  f.  o.  b.  point  of  production.  However,  these 
exceptions  may  not  conflict  seriously  with  the  general  use  of  the  freight 
equalization  system  in  the  industry  because  the  sale  of  prison-made 
twine  is  confined  largely  to  the  States  in  which  it  is  produced,  partly 
on  account  of  restrictions  imposed  by  other  States  upon  imports  of 
prison-made  goods. 

•'  Many  chain  stores  maintain  central  offices  in  New  York  at  which  they  accept  delivery  for  distribution 
to;  their  branches;  this  increases  the  pressure  to  favor  the  New  York  market. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  303 

The  freight  equalization  points  in  use  at  the  present  time,  as  reported 
by  two  of  the  largest  manufacturers,  represent,  in  part,  important 
producing  centers  and,  in  part,  ports  of  entry  for  foreign  twine.  These 
latter  points  are:  Baltimore,  Beaumont  (Tex.),  Boston,  Buffalo, 
Chicago,  Corpus  Christi  (Tex.),  Galveston,  Houston,  Lake  Charles 
(La.),  Los  Angeles,  New  Orleans,  New  York,  Norfolk,  Philadelphia, 
Portland  (Oreg.),  Seattle,  and  San  Francisco.  Until  1937  equalization 
was  largely  on  the  basis  of  domestic  producing  centers  but  the  practice 
was  then  extended  to  include  the  ports  mentioned.  The  significance 
of  import  competition  is  increased  by  the  fact  that  there  is  no  duty 
upon  binder  twine. 

The  system  of  freight  equalization  which  has  been  described  is  not 
always  observed  closely.  There  is  evidence  of  considerable  price 
variation  on  specific  orders  as,  for  example,  on  large-scale  purchases 
made  by  groups  of  dealers  who  pool  their  orders. 

Manila  Rope. — According  to  a  recent  study,  manila  rope  is  sold  by 
at  least  one  manufacturer  with  full  freight  allowed  to  distributors; 
a  practice  equivalent  to  uniform  delivered  prices.  ^* 

LEATHER  AND  ITS  MAJOR  PRODUCTS 

Leather  and  leather  footwear  are  usually  sold  f.  o.  b.  tannery  and 
factory  respectively.  There  is  apparently  little  tendency  to  deviate 
from  uniform  plant  prices  in  either  case. 

Leather. — The  f .  o.  b.  tannery  method  of  selling  is  adhered  to  closely. 
Such  departures  as  do  occur  are  usually  confined  to  periods  of  very 
slack  business.  Freight  absorption  or  equalization  to  meet  the  compe- 
tition of  more  favorably  located  producers  is  uncommon. 

The  minor  importance  of  transportation  charges  in  the  cost  of  the 
finished  product  is  presumably  the  principal  reason  for  adherence  to 
simple  f.  o.  b.  plant  tannery  pricing.  Freight  revenue  on  carload  ship^ 
ments  of  leather  represented  only  1.3  percent  of  value  of  product  at 
destination  during  1936,  according  to  the  Interstate  Commerce  Com- 
mission.^^ In  addition,  there  are  apparently  individual  variations  in 
the  quality  and  grade  of  leather  which  lessen  the  importance  of  price 
comparisons  and  make  it  possible  for  differently  located  tanneries  to 
compete  in  the  same  market  despite  minor  variations  in  their  shipping 
costs. 

Leather  boots  and  shoes. — F.  o.  b.  factory  pricing  is  adhered  to  on 
sales  of  boots  and  shoes  even  more  closely  than  in  the  case  of  leather. 
The  considerations  which  make  this  possible  are  the  same  in  principle 
but  are  even  more  pronounced  than  in  the  leather  market.  There  are 
no  data  regarding  the  ratio  of  freight  revenue  to  delivered  value  on 
raU  shipments  of  boots  and  shoes,  but  it  seems  probable  that  this  ratio 
is  lower  than  for  leather  because  of  the  higher  unit  value  of  the  finished 
product.  The  extensive  use  of  trucks  for  shipment  probably  reduces 
freight  costs  considerably.  In  addition,  differences  in  grade  and  qual- 
ity of  product  are  greater  than  for  leather  and  consumer  acceptance 
of  rival  lines  is  largely  affected  by  the  use  of  trade-marks  and  brands 
which  lessen  the  importance  of  price  considerations  and  make  it 

«  Mund,  V.  A.,  op.  cit.,  p.  237. 

"  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  op,  cit. 


304  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

generally  possible  to  ignore  transportation  costs  as  a  competitive 
factor.  Tie-ups  of  long  standing  between  manufacturers  and  dis- 
tributors may  be  another  factor  making  for  simple  f.  o.  b.  plant  pricing. 
Leather  transmission  belting. — Leather  transmission  belting,  in  lots 
of  100  pounds  or  more,  is  sold  with  full  freight  allowed  to  destination, 
at  least  by  some  manufacturers.^" 

TOBACCO  PRODUCTS 

Cigarettes  and  tobacco. — Cigarettes,  and  smoking  and  chewing 
tobacco  are  sold  at  uniform  delivered  prices  anywhere  in  the  United 
States.  This  practice  is  presumably  dictated  by  the  desire  to  maintain 
a  certain  degree  of  uniformity  of  retail  prices  to  consumers,  although 
cigarette  manufacturers  do  not  as  a  rule  resort  to  such  steps  as  price 
maintenance.  Since  distributive  margins  for  cigarettes  are  not  very 
liberal  it  would  be  difficult  for  distributors  to  absorb  freight  differences. 

PrevaiUng  practices  are  described  in  detail  by  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission  in  its  Agricultural  Income  Inquiry: 

The  prices  and  terms  quoted  on  cigarettes,  smoking  and  chewing  tobacco 
include  freight  delivery  to  the  customer's  railroad  destination.  *  *  *  In  a 
few  cities  certain  manufacturers  make  store-door  deliveries  to  their  customers, 
but  such  instances  are  rare.  In  cities  where  railroads  have  instituted  store-door 
deliveries  the  customer  receives  the  benefit  of  this  arrangement. 

Manufacturers  accept  occasional  collect  telegraphic  orders  from  their  customers, 
make  deliveries  by  express  and  bear  the  cost  of  the  telegram  and  express  charges. 
They  endeavor  to  prevent  an  abuse  of  this  method  of  ordering  and  try  to  hold 
their  customers  to  the  use  of  telegraph  and  express  orders  in  cases  actually  amount- 
ing to  emergencies.  Some  manufacturers'  price  lists  set  out  in  detail  the  arrange- 
ments or  adjustments  which  will  be  made  with  a  customer  on  express  shipments. 

Tobacco  products  generally  and  cigarettes  in  particular  have  a  very  rapid 
turnover  in  retail  establishments.  Manufacturers  consider  it  important  to  keep 
an  adequate  supply  of  their  brands  in  the  hands  of  jobbers  and  retailers  and 
almost  as  important  to  avoid  overstocking  them  and  thus  allowing  stale  mer- 
chandise to  reach  the  consumer.  It  is  said  that  the  use  of  a  recently  developed 
moisture-proof  wrapping  has  materially  lengthened  the  period  of  freshness,  but 
it  is  still  necessary  for  tobacco  products  to  move  rapidly  through  the  channels  of 
distribution. 

These  considerations,  as  well  as  delivery  costs,  make  it  important  for  manu- 
facturers, particularly  those  whose  products  are  distributed  nationally,  to  use 
service  depots  near  their  centers  of  distribution.  The  larger  manufacturers 
utilize  the  services  of  public  warehouses,  consigning  merchandise  to  such  ware- 
houses from  time  to  time  to  supply  the  needs  of  the  trade  in  those  areas.  The 
goods  are  stored  by  the  warehouse  company  and  delivered  by  it  on  order  of  the 
manufacturer.  Although  more  than  one  manufacturer  may  use  the  services  of 
the  same  public  warehouse,  it  does  not  appear  that  there  are  any  joint  arrange- 
ments among  manufacturers  concerning  the  use  of  such  warehouses.  Several 
manufacturers  operate  their  own  distributing  warehouses  on  the  Pacific  coast, 
but  this  is  a  departure  from  the  usual  method. 

Deliveries  of  goods  sold  to  chain-store  companies  are  usually  made  directly 
fronfi  the  factory  to  the  warehouse  of  the  chain.  Customers  of  this  type  usually 
receive  the  same  terms  as  jobbers  and  they  are  expected  to  service  their  individual 
stores.  In  some  instances  manufacturers  make  drop  shipments  to  individual 
stores  of  a  chain.  These  have  sometimes  represented  as  much  as  50  percent  of 
the  total  sales  of  cigarettes  to  a  particular  chain  but  such  instances  are  unusual. 

Nearly  all  manufacturers  make  drop  shipments  of  certain  minimum  quantities 
or  combinations  of  brands  directly  to  retailers  for  the  accounts  of  jobbers.  Often 
such  shipments  include  free  goods  or  special  allowances  to  retailers  and  in  some 
instances  jobbers  are  given  additional  allowances.  Some  manufacturers  will 
make  drop  shipments  of  quantities  as  low  as  1,000  cigarettes,  or  5  cartons.  In 
this  way  it  is  possible  for  consumers  to  order  through  customers  of  the  manu- 

'«  Mund,  V.  A.,  op.  cit.,  p.  233. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  305 

facturer  in  quantities  small  enough  for  their  personal  use  or  for  division  with 
others.  Such  shipments  are  made  by  the  manufacturer  on  the  order  of  his 
customer,  and  when  they  are  in  interstate  commerce  state  stamp  taxes  are. avoided. 
This  type  of  merchandising  does  not  appear  to  be  engaged  in  to  any  substantial 
extent  at  the  present  time.^' 

Cigars. — Cigars  are  also  usually  sold  on  a  uniform  delivered  price 
basis.     According  to  the  Federal  Trade  Commission: 

Only  one  instance  was  found  where  a  cigar  manufacturer  made  sales  f.  o.  b. 
factory  and  in  this  instance  a  trade  discount  of  12}'^  percent,  plus  the  customary 
cash  discount,  was  given.  No  additional  discounts  or  allowances  are  given  to 
direct  customers  of  manufacturers  on  account  of  quantity  purchased.  Additional 
allowances  are  made  to  indirect  cuctomers,  including  customers  of  branch  houses, 
in  drop-shipment  deals,  and  occasionally  an  extra  allowance  is  made  to  the 
distributor  for  securing  drop-shipment  orders.^^ 

Snuff. — In  contrast  to  the  other  tobacco  products  described,  snuff 
is  sold  on  a  zone  basis.  There  are  five  recognized  zones  in  the  United 
States,  two  of  which  include  the  single  States  of  Kentucky  and 
Virginia.  However,  price  variation  between  zones  is  not  the  same 
for  all  producers.  In  all  cases  reported  by  the  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission,^^ the  price  in  the  Northeast  is  between  4  and  6  percent  lower 
than  in  the  region  west  of  the  Mississippi  and  north  of  Oklahoma. 
Two  of  the  three  producers  charge  the  same  price  in  the  South  as  in 
the  East,  while  the  other  quotes  the  higher  western  price  in  the  South. 
Further  minor  differences  are  introduced  by  variations  in  discounts 
and  other  terms  of  sale. 

STEEL  AND  STEEL  PRODUCTS 

The  geographic  pricing  practices  used  by  the  steel  industry  were 
described  in  detail  at  hearings  recently  held  by  the  Temporary  Na- 
tional Economic  Committee.^*  Consequently,  only  the  salient  fea- 
tures of  the  system  will  be  recapitulated  here. 

The  steel  industry  represents  probably  the  best  known  illustration 
of  a  multiple  basing  point  system.  For  each  major  group  of  products, 
such  as  structural  shapes,  tank  plates,  bars,  hot  rolled  sheets,  cold 
rolled  sheets,  galvanized  sheets,  etc.,  "base  prices"  are  quoted  at  a 
number  of  basing  points.  Basing  points  are  not  the  same  for  all 
classes  of  product  but  vary,  depending  partly  upon  the  actual  loca- 
tion of  producing  mills.  For  a  specialized  product  such  as  tin  plate, 
the  number  of  recognized  basing  points  will  be  less  than  for  those 
whose  production  is  more  widely  distributed,  such  as  structural  shapes 
or  hot  rolled  sheets. 

These  "base  prices"  apply  to  orders  of  a  specified  character  and 
quantity.  The  actual  price  "f.  o.  b.  basing  point"  for  any  particular 
order  can  be  computed  from  this  base  price  by  the  application  of  a 
detailed  schedule  of  extras  and  deductions. 

The  delivered  price  on  any  order  at  any  point  will  then  be,  at  least 
nominally,  the  lowest  sum  of  any  basing  point  price,  corrected  by  the 
application  of  the  relevant  extras  or  deductions,  and  of  freight  from 
that  basing  point  to  the  point  of  delivery.     Freight  rates  used  are 

"  Federal  Trade  Commission — Agricultural  Income  Inquiry,  1937,  pt.  I,  pp.  519,  520. 

» Ibid.,  p.  522. 

"  Ibid.,  pp.  478-479. 

"  See  Hearings,  Part  27.  January' 27-29,  1940 


306  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

compiled  in  a  freight  book  which  is  pubUshed  by  the  American  Iron 
and  Steel  Institute  and  are  usually  based  upon  all-rail  rate.^^ 

For  most  important  products,  there  is  a  tendency  for  base  prices  at 
various  basing  points  used  to  be  uniform,  but  there  is  some  variation. 
For  soft  steel  bars,  for  example,  prices  as  of  February  8,  1940,  were 
the  same  at  Pittsburgh,  Chicago  and  Gary,  Cleveland,  Buffalo,  and 
Birmingham.  The  base  price  at  Duluth  was  slightly  higher,  while 
prices  were  also  quoted  f.  o.  b.  cars  at  Gulf  ports  and  Pacific  ports  at 
levels  above  those  for  all  basing  points.  Similarly,  for  cold  rolled 
sheets,  the  base  price  at  Granite  City  was  higher  than  at  Middletown, 
Cleveland,  Buffalo,  Chicago,  Youngstown,  and  Pittsburgh,  all  of  the 
latter  being  uniform.^^  In  general,  the  price  quoted  f.  o.  b.  Gulf 
ports  or  Pacific  ports  approximate  the  base  price  at  the  nearest  eastern 
producing  center  plus  combined  rail-water  freight. 

The  Iron  Age,  which  is  the  recognized  source  of  price  quotations  for 
the  industry,  also  quotes  delivered  prices  for  New  York  and  Phila- 
delphia. It  is  understood,  however,  that  these  delivered  prices  are 
nothing  more  than  base  prices  plus  all-rail  freight 

For  a  few  items,  such  as  soft  steel  bars  and  hot  and  cold  rolled 
sheets,  there  is  also  a  delivered  price  quotation  at  Detroit.  This  last 
quotation  is  usually  "arbitrary"  in  the  sense  that  it  is  below  the  figure 
which  would  be  arrived  at  by  adding  freight  to  the  price  at  the  nearest 
basing  point. 

Freight  charges  in  almost  all  cases  are  based  upon  all-rail  freight. 
It  is,  however,  usually  permissible  for  the  buyer  to  accept  delivery 
from  the  plant  in  trucks,  but  in  such  a  case  he  must  pay  35  percent  of 
the  published  all-rail  freight  to  destination  in  addition  to  the  base 
price.  According  to  testimony  presented  at  the  hearings  before  the 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  this  premium  is  added  in 
order  to  discourage  truck  shipments  because  of  the  extra  costs  to 
producers  said  to  be  involved  in  making  truck  delivery .^^  In  general 
there  is  no  provision  for  making  use  of  water  shipments  in  order  to 
reduce  freight  costs.  According  to  representatives  of  the  industry, 
the  purpose  of  this  practice  is  to  avoid  giving  an  advantage  to  cus- 

35  Thus,  according  to  the  testimony  of  Mr.  Fairless,  chairman  of  the  board  of  the  United  States  Steel  Cor- 
portation,  before  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee: 

"Mr.  Fairless.  The  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute  has  a  traCBc  committpe  composed  of  traflBc  man- 
agers of  10  different  steel  companies.  This  committee  supervises  the  institutes  Freitrht  Rate  Book.  There 
are  four  sections  to  the  Institutes  Rale  Book,  and  the  responsibility  of  keeping  these  sections  up  to  date  is 
assigned  to  different  members  of  the  committee. 

"When  corrections  are  necessary— and  by  necessary  I  mean  when  rate  changes  take  place— these  com- 
mittee members  have  the  changes  made  on  supplementary  sections  or  pages,  sending  these  sections  or  pages 
to  the  institute  for  distribution  to  holders  of  the  rate  book.  The  rate  book  is  availablo  to  anyone  internstcd 
in  the  steel  business,  but  peculiarly,  it  is  not  used  by  all  the  steel  companies  and  is  used  by  some  manufac- 
turing concerns  not  classed  as  steel  companies.  There  is  a  nominal  charge  made  for  this  service  and  the 
individual  holders  of  the  book  pay  these  charges  to  the  institute."  See  Temporary  National  Economic 
Committee  IJnarinss,  Part  27,  morning  session,  January  27,  ]04(). 

3«  Iron  Age.     February  8.  1940. 

3'  On  this  point  Mr.  Adams,  President  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  testified  to  this  effect 
before  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee.- 

"Mr.  Adams.  On  truck  deliveries  where  we  contract  with  a  common  carrier,  the  truck  company,  to 
deliver  our  products  to  destination,  we  charge  the  all-rail  rato  of  freipht.  We  do  that  because  in  our  analysis 
of  rail  rates  versus  truck  rates  we  find  that  there  is  practically  no  difference.  There  may  be  a  difference 
of  a  few  cents  here  or  there,  but  generally  speaiing  they  are  approximately  the  same.  If  we  sell  our  material 
on  a  delivered-price  basis,  as  we  always  do,  and  a  buyer  wants  to  send  his  truck  to  our  mill  to  pick  up  that 
material,  we  quote  the  delivered  price  predicated  upon  a  transportation  cost  which  is  equsl  to  the  rail  rate 
and  we  deduct  from  that  66  percent  of  that  rate.  Our  object  in  doing  that  is  something  that  we  do  not 
attempt  to  conceal. 

"We  are  attempting  to  discourage  ine  use  of  trucks  in  the  transportation  of  our  products  for  many  reasons. 
In  the  first  place,  our  production  facilities  are  not  laid  out  to  haul  all  of  our  products  by  tryck,  smaU  truck 
loads.  We  couldn't  possibly  ship  12  to  15  millions  of  finished  products  throughout  this  country  each  year 
and  use  trucks;  there  is  not  enough  space  in  our  plants  to  handle  trucks  on  that  basis,  so  it  is  an  attempt  on 
our  part  to  discourage  the  use  of  trucks  in  the  handling  of  steel  products.  Also  there  is  the  question  of  the 
material  being  damaged  in  transit  and  other  items  of  that  character."  (See  Hearings,  Part  27,  after- 
noon session,  January  26,  1940.) 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  3Q7 

tomers  located  on  waterways  as  against  those  who  could  not  con- 
veniently use  water  shipment.  According  to  executives  of  the  United 
States  Steel  Corporation  only  1.6  percent  of  the  total  steel  tonnage 
actually  moves  by  water  at  the  all-rail  freight  rate.^^  It  is  possible, 
however,  that  the  volume  of  water  shipment  would  be  larger  if  cus- 
tomers were- permitted  to  take  advantage  of  the  resulting, economies. 

On  shipments  to  customers  located  at  a  basing  point,  a  switching 
charge  is  added  which  is  uniform  on  all  transfers  within  the  basing 
point  regardless  of  the  actual  location  of  the  seller  or  the  buyer. 

Although  the  tendency  of  this  system,  insofar  as  it  is  observed,  is 
to  equalize  the  quotations  of  all  sellers  m  each  market,  there  will  be 
differences  in  certain  cases  because  of  the  availability  of  fabrication- 
in-transit  rates.  Through  the  use  of  these  rates  there  is  a  single 
freight  charge  covering  shipment  from  the  steel  mill  to  the  fabricator 
and  from  the  fabricator  to  the  destination,  and  this  single  rate  is  less 
than  the  smn  of  the  two  straight-haul  rates  involved.  As  a  result,  a 
fabricator  may  obtain  an  advantage  by  ordering  his  steel  from  a  mill 
located  at  some  distance  from  his  plant,  rather  than  from  one  nearby, 
because  the  low  through  rate  permits  him  to  save  a  substantial  portion 
of  the  cost  of  shipping  the  fabricated  product  to  the  job.  Some  of 
the  consequences  of  the  availability  of  this  privilege  were  suggested 
by  Dr.  De  Chazeau,  associate  professor  of  economics  at  the  University 
of  Virginia,  testifying  before  the  Committee: 

Incoming  waybills  (i.  e.,  waybills  on  the  shipment  from  mill  to  fabricating 
plant)  may  be  accumulated  by  the  fabricating  plant  and  used  on  outgoing  ship- 
ments of  equal  tonnage  which  permit  the  greatest  saving  to  the  fabricator.  So 
long  as  foreign  mills  arc  willing  to  quote  him,  therefore,  it  is  profitable  for  the 
fabricator  to  purchase  his  stec!  from  the  foreign  rather  than  from  the  home  mill. 
For  example,  through  the  application  of  incoming  way-bills  on  shipments  to 
paiticular  areas,  the  fatricator  may  save  up  to  five  or  six  dollars  a  ton.  Obviously 
the  saving  depends  entirely  on  the  destination,  on  the  freight  rate  structure,  and 
on  the  source  of  supply;  but  the  advantage  (for  purposes  of  f-i-t)  in  buying  from 
a  contieruous  mill  is  very  small. 

The  price  to  the  faliricator  at  his  plant  is  the  same  from  both  mills.  But  if 
he  is  at  Neville  Inland,  say  (within  the  switching  limits  of  Pittsburgh),  and  he 
buys  from  a  Pittsburgh  plant,  thtTe  is  no  advantage  in  f-i-t.  The  maximum 
difference  lietween  the  through  rate  from  the  Pittsburgh  mill  to  destination  of 
the  fabricated  material  and  the  sum  of  the  two  local  rates  is  not  more  than  a  few 
cents.  However,  if  he  can  get  his  steel  from  Chicago  in  shipments  to  certain 
destinations  the  difference  will  be  substantial  and  effects  a  reduction  in  the  cost 
of  steel  to  him  at  ultimate  destination.  The  saving  varies  up  to  about  five  or 
six  dollars  a  ton.  I  don't  assume  that  is  the  average;  the  average  is  likely  to  be 
considerably  less.  Thus,  if  the  home  mill  is  to  retain  its  business,  it  must  cut  the 
price  to  compensate  the  fabricator  for  foregoing  his  f-i-t  privilege.^" 

It  was  stressed  at  the  hearings  before  the  Temporary  National  Eco- 
nomic Committee  that  the  price  structure  for  steel  is  not  always 
rigidly  adhered  to  and  that  concessions  are  granted  from  time  to  time 
as  market  conditions  warrant.  During  the  summer  of  1939,  for  ex- 
ample, according  to  this  testimony,  discounts  amounted  to  from  $6  to 
$8  per  ton.  The  effect  of  these  concessions  as  a  factor  modifying  the 
normal  geographic  structure  depends  upon  whether  they  are  uniformly 
extended  to  all  buyers,  wherever  located,  or  whether  the  actual  cost 
of  shipment  is  a  factor  in  determining  the  willingness  of  the  seller  to 
reduce  his  prices  on  particular  orders. 

"Ibid. 

'•  See  Hearine.s.  Part  27,  morning  session,  January  26,  lfl40. 


308  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Other  iron  and  steel  products. — Lake  Superior  iron  ore  is  usually 
quoted  "delivered  lake  ports."  Imported  ores  are  usually  priced 
c.  i.  f.  seaboard. 

Some  light  steel  products,  such  as  bolts,  nuts,  and  rivets,  are  sold 
on  a  freight-equalized  basis.  The  price  is  f .  o.  b.  seller's  works,  freight 
equalized  with  Cleveland,  Pittsburgh,  Chicago,  or  Birmingham.  This 
system  differs  from  a  true  basing-point  sj'^stem  in  that  the  price  at 
the  seller's  works  will  never  be  higher  than  that  at  points  remote  from 
the  seller's  works. 

Ferro-alloys. — The  practice  with  regard  to  ferro-alloys  varies.  Fer- 
romanganese  is  quoted  f.  o.  b.  Atlantic  and  Gulf  ports  (New  York, 
Philadelphia,  Baltimore,  Mobile,  and  New  Orleans).  Bessemer  ferro- 
silicon  and  silvery  iron  are  sold  on  a  basing-point  system,  f.  o.  b. 
Jackson  (Ohio)  or  Buffalo  (N.  Y.).  Electric  ferrosilicon,  ferrochrome, 
silico  manganese,  and  many  other  alloys  are  priced  on  a  uniform  de- 
livered basis. 

Hardware,  tools,  and  other  light  fabricated  steel. — Such  products  as 
-cap  and  set  screws,  screw  products,  stove  bolts,  tire  chains,  machine 
knives,  furniture  tacks,  and  steel  pulleys  are  generally  sold  f .  o.  b. 
plant  with  full  freight  allowed  to  destination.  Usually  some  limita- 
tion regarding  the  size  of  shipment  and  sometimes  the  amount  of  the 
allowance  is  specified;  for  example,  for  cap  and  set  screws  and  stove 
bolts  the  allowance  is  not  to  exceed  65  cents  per  100  pounds  on  orders 
of  200  pounds  or  more.  For  some  items,  such  as  sash  pulleys  and 
saws,  freight  is  allowed  within  given  zones.  For  pliers,  wrenches, 
screw  drivers,  and  many  other  small  tools,  freight  is  allowed  to  dis- 
tributors or  to  distributing  points.^'' 

LUMBER    AND    ITS    PRODUCTS 

Although  conventional  forms  of  geographic  pricing  practices  have 
been  developed  in  the  market  for  most  lumber  products,  the  verj^ 
large  number  of  competing  mills,  the  multiplicity  of  grades  and  sizes, 
and  competition  between  different  varieties  precludes  their  rigid  ob- 
servance. Consequently  the  types  of  geographic  price  structure  de- 
scribed below  should  not  be  interpreted  as  constituting  more  than  the 
usual  or  prevailing  practice. 

Lumber — Douglas  jir .—The  general  practice  is  to  quote  prices  either 
f.  o.  b.  mill  or  f.  o.  b.  destination  and  to  equalize  delivered  prices  in 
an  unsystematic  manner  in  order  to  meet  competition.  However, 
individual  mills  may  choose  not  to  sell  in  territories  in  which  exces- 
sive freight  absorption  is  required.  For  example,  one  west-coast 
manufacturer  does  not  compete  within  the  territory  between  the  Mis- 
sissippi River  and  the  Rocky  Mountains  because  of  the  existence  of 
more  favorably  located  mills  on  the  eastern  slope  of  the  Rockies.  He 
will,  however,  ship  to  the  east  coast  by  boat  because  of  the  low  water 
freight  rates  prevailing.  In  general,  mills  located  on  the  West  Coast 
are  more  favorably  situated  with  regard  to  the  east-coast  market  than 
are  mUls  farther  inland. 

Lumber — Ponderosa  pine. — The  geographic  price  structure  for  Pon- 
derosa  pine  is  generally  the  same  as  that  for  Douglas  fir  except  that 

*'>  These  statements  are  based  partly  upon  information,  contained  in  the  Iron  Age,  and  partly  upon  data 
compiled  by  Mund  (op.  cit.  pp  233-237).  While  these  practices  are  reported  by  some  manufacturers, 
there  is  no  evidence  to  indicate  whether  their  observance  is  universal. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  3Q9 

the  source  of  this  lumber  extends  farther  east  and  south  than  does 
that  for  Douglas  fir. 

Lumber — Southern  pine. — Southern  pine  is  quoted  on  what  approxi- 
mates a  multiple  basing-point  system,  with  bases  at  Norfolk  (Va.), 
Hattiesburg  (Miss.),  and  the  Raleigh  mountain  district  of  North  Caro- 
lina. This  system  is  observed  more  commonly  by  large  mills  than  by 
small;  the  latter  adjust  their  prices  in  most  markets  to  meet  competi- 
tion. In  areas  adjacent  to  Atlantic  ports,  such  as  Baltimore,  southern 
pine  comes  into  direct  competition  with  western  softwood  shipped  by 
water.  Prices  will  usually  be  modified  accordingly  to  meet  this  com- 
petition. 

Maple  flooring. — Maple  flooring  is  sold  on  a  single  basing-point 
system.     Prices  are  quoted  f.  o.  b.  Cadillac,  Mich. 

Oak  flooring. — Oak  flooring  is  sold  on  a  multiple  basing  point  system, 
with  bases  at  Johnson  City  and  Memphis  (Tenn.)  and  Alexandria 
(La.).  Prices  are  quoted  f.  o.  b.  destination  and  include  full  freight 
from  the  basing  point  most  favorably  situated.  The  computed  freight 
is  rounded  at  50-cent  intervals;  thus  a  mill  quotation  of  $65  per  thou- 
sand board  feet  in  carlots  plus  a  freight  charge  of  $7.80  would  be 
quoted  f.  o.  b.  destination  at  $73  per  thousand  board  feet. 

Philippine  mahogany. — Although  Philippine  mahogany  is  not  a  true 
mahogany,  it  is  directly  competitive  with  Honduran,  African,  and 
Cuban  mahogany  for  most  purposes.  It  is  sold  on  a  smgle  basing- 
point  system,  f.  o.  b.  San  Francisco,  Calif. 

Mahogany — Honduran,  African,  and  Cuban. — These  varieties  of  true 
mahogany  are  sold  at  delivered  prices  which  are,  at  least  nominally, 
uniform  throughout  the  United  States.  However,  it  is  understood 
that  prices  may  be  varied  to  meet  the  competition  of  other  hardwoods 
and  particularly  of  Philippine  mahogany. 

Doors — Douglas  fir  and  Ponderosa  pine. — A  zone-price  structure  is 
observed  in  the  sale  of  doors  and  prices  are  quoted  f.  o.  b.  destination. 
One  manufacturer  lists  21  zones  in  which  he  competes,  but  the  prices 
in  2  or  more  zones  may  be  the  same.  The  method  of  price  quotation 
for  this  product  is  a  varying  discount  off  a  nominal  fixed  list  price. 

Windows  and  vdndow  frames. — Windows  and  window  frames  are 
also  quoted  by  varying  discounts  from  a  nominal  list  price.  Plants 
are  small  and  more  widely  distributed  than  for  doors.  The  sales 
territory  of  individual  plants  is  usually  circumscribed  and  sales  are 
made  at  uniform  delivered  prices  anywhere  in  this  territory. 

Wooden  boxes. — Wooden  boxes  are  usually  quoted  either  delivered 
to  destination  or  f.  o.  b.  plant  with  a  maximum  freight  allowance. 
Of  three  quotations  reported  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics,  two 
are  on  tiie  former  basis  and  one  on  the  latter. 

Wooden  caskets  and  coflins. — Wooden  caskets  are  also  usually  quoted 
either  delivered  to  destination  or  f .  o.  b.  plant  with  a  maximum  freight 
allowance. 

Axe  handles. — Axe  handles  are  quoted  on  a  delivered  basis  east  of 
the  Rocky  Mountains  and  on  a  basis  o  a  maximum  freight  allowance 
west  of  the  Rocky  Mountains. 

Ladders. — Quotations  are  usually  f.  o.  b.  factory  with  freight  allow- 
ances limited  either  as  to  territory  or  amount.  In  some  cases  freight 
will  be  allowed  only  on  shipments  exceeding  a  specified  weight,  such  as 
100  pounds  or  200  pounds.  Several  manufacturers  allow  only  the 
carload  rates  on  1.  c.  1.  shipments. 


310  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Plywood. — Quotations  for  plywood  in  the  Engineering  News  Record 
indicate  the  existence  of  a  single  basing  point  at  Seattle,  Wash.  A 
series  of  rail-freight  increments  for  various  points  in  the  country  is 
published  together  with  this  base  quotation.  However,  the  buyer 
may  take  advantage  of  water  shipment  to  reduce  the  delivered  price 
in  case  he  is  located  at  or  near  a  seaboard. 

Summary. — The  prevailing  geographic  price  structures  for  these 
products  are  summarized  below. 

Lumber— Douglas  fir:  Unsystematic  freight  equalization. 

Lumber — Ponderosa  pine:  Unsystematic  freight  equalization. 

Lumber — southern  pine:  Multiple  basing  point,  subject  to  equalization  for 
competing  varieties. 

Maple  flooring:  Single  basing  point. 

Oak  flooring:  Multiple  basing  point. 

Philippine  mahogany:  Single  basing  point. 

Mahogany-Honduran,  African,  Cuban:  Uniform  delivered  prices. 

Doors — Douglas  fir  and  Ponderosa  pine:  Zone  delivered  prices. 

Windows  and  window  frames:  Uniform  delivered  prices,  area  of  shipment 
limited. 

Wooden  boxes:  Uniform  delivered  prices  or  limited  freight  allowance. 

Wooden  caskets  and  coffins:  Uniform  delivered  prices  or  limited  freight  allow- 
ance. 

Axe  handles:  Uniform  delivered  prices  or  limited  freight  allowance. 

Ladders:  Limited  freight  allowance. 

Plywood:  Single  basing  point. 

TURPENTINE 

Turpentine  is  usually  sold  on  a  delivered  basis  but  the  price  is  said 
to  include  full  freight  from  plant  in  each  instance.  Sellers  will  quote 
f.  o.  b.  plant  prices  but  this  will  involve  no  difference  in  the  net  price 
dehvered. 

The  ability  of  turpentine  producers  to  maintain  uniform  plant 
realizations  for  a  standard  product  of  this  character  may  be  explained 
by  the  high  concentration  of  the  producing  area.  Of  a  total  value  of 
product  for  1935  of  $19,000,000,  $10,000,000  was  produced  in  Georgia 
and  $18,000,000  in  the  3  States,  Georgia,  Florida,  and  Alabama. 
Consequently,  freight  differentials  between  rival  producers  are  unlikely 
to  bo  important. 

BUILDING  MATERIALS  OTHER  THAN  STEEL  AND  LUMBER  PRODUCTS 

Although  building  materials  cover  a  very  wide  range  of  commodities, 
they  have  many  market  characteristics  in  common.  The  most  im- 
portant of  these,  from  the  point  of  view  of  geographic  price  structures, 
is  their  relatively  low  price  per  unit  of  weight,  with  the  result  that 
transportation  charges  in  most  cases  form  a  very  appreciable  part  of 
their  delivered  price.  For  some  items  in  this  group,  in  fact,  trans- 
portation costs  are  so  great  that  they  cannot  be  shipped  over  long 
distances;  brick,  sand,  and  gravel,  for  example,  have  distinctly  local 
markets.  Moreover,  since  they  are  usually  sold  not  to  the  ultimate 
consumer  but  to  building  contractors,  the  significance  of  brand  names 
as  a  factor  directing  competition  into  nonprice  channels  is  usually 
limited.  In  addition,  there  is  possible  a  substantial  degree  of  substi- 
tution of  one  material  for  another;  thus  lumber,  steel,  and  reinforced 
concrete  ma}^  all  be  used  for  similar  purposes.  Consequently  com- 
parisons of  delivered  prices  play  an  important  role  in  competition. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


311 


This  has  been  reflected  in  the  case  of  most  building  materials  in  the 
development  of  more  or  less  elaborate  systems  for  equalizing  freight. 

The  following  discussion  is  concerned  with  building  materials  other 
than  steel  and  lumber  which,  because  of  their  major  economic  im- 
portance, have  been  accorded  separate  treatment. 

Lime. — Lime  is  sold  at  delivered  prices  which  are  determined  on 
the  basis  of  a  system  of  freight  equalization.  The  price  at  any  locality 
is  the  lowest  sum  of  any  applicable  plant  price  plus  freight  from  that 
plant.  Plant  prices  and  freight  rate  schedules  are  both  published, 
so  that  it  is  possible  for  each  seller  to  quote  the  same  delivered  price 
in  any  market  in  which  he  chooses  to  compete.  In  general,  sales  Will 
not  be  rftade  when  the  amount  of  freight  absorption  required  is  con- 
sidered excessive.  According  to  members  of  the  industry,  price  cut- 
ting below  the  accepted  level  is  approved  only  in  "cases  of  emergency." 
Such  an  "emergency"  is  described,  for  example,  as  a  situation  in  which 
a  carload  of  lime  is  misdirected  through  an  error  in  the  traffic  depart- 
ment, with  the  result  that  a  lower  price  must  be  accepted  in  order  to 
avoid  the  necessity  of  paying  freight  or  storage. 

The  following  table  indicates  the  extent  of  variation  of  the  delivered 
prices  of  hydrated  lime  in  the  major  geographic  regions  of  the  United 
States,  as  reported  to  the  Bureai.  of  Labor  Statistics.  For  each  region 
the  highest  and  lowest  prices  recorded  are  sho^\Ti. 

Lime  {hydrated,  Mason's) — Variations  in  delivered  prices  for  selected  destinations 
within  major  geographic  regions 


Region 

Price  per  ton 

1 

Region 

Price  per  ton 

High 

Low 

High 

Low 

New  England.. 

$11. 69 
9.70 
10.50 
13.30 

$10. 81 
9.55 
9.60 
11.30 

South  /  tlantic 

$14.  89 
13.40 
13.80 
19.70 

$8.00 

Middle  Atlantic 

East  Soi  th  Central-  . 

10.35 

East  North  Central 

West  So ath  Central.. 

11.80 

West  North  Central. 

Mountain  and  Pacific 

15.50 

Cement. — Cement  is  sold  in  accordance  with  a  multiple  basing  point 
system.  The  delivered  price  is  determined  in  each  instance  by  the 
usual  method  of  taking  the  lowest  sum  of  any  applicable  base  price 
plus  freight. 

The  system  as  it  now  exists  represents  a  gradual  evolution  from  a 
single  basing  point  in  the  Lehigh  Valley,  which  was  once  thought  to 
constitute  the  only  acceptable  source  of  raw  material.  As  new  plants 
were  established  in  other  areas,  there  was  a  tendency  for  additional 
basing  points  to  be  added,  though  the  process  of  readjustment  often 
involved  severe  price  wars.  At  the  present  time  a  fairly  large  number 
of  territories  has  become  recognized,  each  of  which  is  permitted  to 
determine  its  own  basing  point  structure;  mills  from  outside  of  this 
area  do  not  usually  cut  under  this  price  structure  when  they  ship 
into  it. 

The  basing  point  structure  is  modified  by  the  existence  of  a  few 
arbitrary  points,  such  as  New  York  City,  in  which  the  delivered  price 
is  adjusted  to  meet  the  competition  of  imports  and  is  not  directly 
related  to  the  price  prevailing  at  the  nearest  basing  point. 

Variations  in  delivered  prices  are  shown  below. 


-4711!!— 41  — No.  1- 


-22 


312 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Cement   (portland)- 


-Variation  in  delivered  prices  for  selected  destinations  within 
major  geographic  regions 


Ecglon 

Price  per  barrel 
(in  cloth) 

Region 

Price  per  barrel 
(in  cloth) 

High 

Low 

High 

Low 

New  England  and  Middle  At- 

$2.25 
1.94 
2.16 

$1.72 
1.55 
1.81 

South  Atlantic. --. 

$2.36 
2  35 
2.93 
2.40 

$1.81 

lantic 

South  Central- 

1.76 

East  North  Central           

Mountain        .  .. 

1  40 

West  North  Central -. 

Pacific      

1.40 

Brick. — Brick  manufacture  and  distribution  is  purely  local,  except 
for  certain  very  high  grade  face  brick,  because  the  high  cost  of  trans- 
portation precludes  shipping  the  product  over  any  considerable  dis- 
tance. It  is  usually  sold  on  the  basis  of  delivery  to  the  job,  with 
prices  uniform  within  any  locality. 

Sand  and  gravel. — Geographic  pricing  practice  is  the  same  as  for 
brick. 

Building  tile. — Building  tile  is  also  largely  a  local  item,  though  the 
radius  of  its  distribution  is  somewhat  greater  than  for  brick.  It, 
too,  is  usually  sold  delivered  to  the  job,  with  prices  uniform  within 
each  local  it3^ 

Floor  tile. — Floor  tile  is  sold  on  a  freight-equalized  basis  with  each 
seller  equalizing  freight  with  his  most  advantageously  located  com- 
petitor. However,  full  freight  equalization  is  applied  only  to  certain 
products  such  as  the  standard  T  inch  wide  hexagon  tile;  for  other 
items  the  amount  of  freight  which  a  manufacturer  will  absorb  is 
limited. 

Sewer  pipe. — Sewer  pipe  is  also  sold  on  a  freight  equalization  basis. 
The  method  of  quotation  is  f.  o.  b.  destination  in  carlots  and  the  ele- 
ment of  equalization  is  introduced  in  calculating  this  destination  price. 

Gypsum  plaster. — The  geographic  price  structure  for  gypsum 
plaster  is  very  similar  to  that  for  lime.  F.  o.  b.  prices  vary  from 
plant  to  plant,  even  for  the  same  company,  and  the  delivered  price 
at  any  point  is  the  lowest  sum  of  plant  price  plus  freight.  In  some 
large  metropolitan  markets,  such  as  New  York  City,  prices  are 
quoted  "flat";  that  is,  on  a  delivered  basis.  Control  in  this  industry 
is  highly  concentrated  and  the  leading  producer  is  in  a  position  to 
determine  and  police  the  price  structure  very  effectively.  The  extent 
of  variation  in  delivered  prices  in  important  cities  in  each  major 
geographic  region  is  shown  below. 


Gypsum^  plaster  (Neat)- 


-Variation  in  delivered  prices  for  selected  destinations  within 
major  geographic  regions 


Region 

Price  per  ton 

Region 

Price  per  ton 

High 

Low 

High 

Low 

New  England 

$12.  20 
9.50 
13.80 
17.00 
15.00 

$9.50 
8.50 
11.50 
13.00 
9.75 

East  South  Central 

$16. 80 
17.40 
17.40 
17.00 

$14.20 

Middle  Atlantic 

West  South  Central        

14.40 

East  North  Central.... 

12.50 

West  North  Central 

Pacific                           

13.40 

South  Atlantic 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


313 


Insulation  board. — Insulation  board  is  sold  on  a  zone-price  system, 
with  most  of  the  large  companies  delivering  in  three  or  four  zones. 
Prices  are  quoted  f.  o.  b.  shipping  point  with  full  freight  allowed  to 
destination.  On  straight  carlot  and  half  carlot  shipments,  delivery 
is  made  to  customers  on  private  rail  siding  or  to  the  freight  station 
or  public  team  track  nearest  destination  or,  in  the  case  of  water  trans- 
portation, to  the  steamship  dock  nearest  destination.  No  allowance 
is  made  for  trucking  from  these  points  to  the  buyer's  warehouse. 
On  1.  c.  1.  shipments,  if  delivery  is  made  by  truck  to  the  customer's 
regularly  estabUshed  warehouse,  trucking  charges  are  allowed  to 
point  of  delivery;  on  rail  shipments  the  allowance  is  to  the  nearest 
rail  destination.  In  no  instance  is  delivery  made  to  a  specific  job 
site.  Although  the  customer  can  apparently  select  his  own  method 
of  delivery,  he  cannot  profit  by  using  cheaper  methods  of  transpor- 
tation such  as  water  carrier,  because  the  freight  allowance  wiU  be 
reduced  correspondingly  and  the  delivered  price  remains  the  same. 

Prepared  roofing. — The  geographic  price  structure  for  prepared 
roofing  is  quite  complex.  Most  companies  publish  detailed  price 
lists  for  the  various  products  and  include  a  detailed  description  of 
their  terms  of  delivery. 

Prices  are  quoted  on  an  f.  o.  b.  shipping  point  basis.  For  certain 
defined  areas  surrounding  a  manufacturer's  factories  and  warehouses, 
full  freight  is  allowed.  Beyond  these  "factory  point"  zones,  freight 
will  be  equalized  to  the  nearest  published  competitive  shipping  point. 
Freight  in  each  instance  is  paid  by  the  buyer  who  deducts  the  amount 
of  the  applicable  freight  allowance  in  paying  the  seller  Quotations 
include  provision  for  adjusting  prices  in  case  a  price  decline  is  an- 
nounced during  transit. 

Not  all  companies  equalize  fully,  nor  on  all  products.  For  example, 
several  manufacturers  limit  their  freight  absorption  to  not  more  than 
30  cents  per  hundred  pounds.  East  of  the  Rocky  Mountains  the 
dealer  plant  price  is  usually  the  same  for  each  plant  operated  by  a 
company.  In  the  West,  however,  prices  are  higher  and  vary  be- 
tween plants. 

The  extent  of  price  variation  for  certain  roofing  products  for  the 
major  geographic  zones  in  the  United  States  is  shown  below. 

Prepared  roofing  (asphalt  strip  shingles,  12  inches,  210  pounds  per  .square) — 
variation  in  delivered  prices  for  selected  destinations  within  major  geographic 
regions 


Region 

Price  per  square 

Region 

Price  per  square 

High 

Low 

mgh 

Low 

New  England 

$4.56 
4.29 
4.39 
4.71 
5.03 

$4.25 
4.25 
4.25 
4.25 
4.25 

East  South  Central 

$4.76 
6.05 
5.93 
4.66 

$4.24 

Middle  Atlantic 

West  South  Central 

4.53 

East  North  Central 

Mountain 

5.03 

West  North  Central 

Pacific             .    

4.14 

South  Atlantic. 

Heating  boilers  and  radiation. — rOeographic  pricing  structure  for 
these  products  varies  for  different  States.  Throughout  most  of  the 
Northeast  a  uniform  delivered  price  prevails;  quotations  are  f.  o.  b. 
manufacturing  or  assembling  plants,  with  full  freight  allowed  to  rail- 
road points  at  destination. 


314  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Throughout  most  of  the  rest  of  the  United  States  prices  will  be 
equalized  with  competitive  points  of  manufacture  or  distribution. 
Where  competing  plants  are  not  a  factor  freight  not  to  exceed  30 
cents  per  hundred  pounds  is  in  any  event  allowed  on  shipments 
f.  o.  b.  manufacturing  pomts,  but  no  freight  allowance  is  granted  under 
such  circumstances  from  assembling  points. 

No  freight  allowance  is  made  on  shipments  of  less  than  100  pounds. 

Plumbing  fixtures,  closets,  lavatories,  sinks,  and  bathtubs. — Three 
leading  manufacturers  in  this  industry  sell  in  carlots  at  uniform 
prices  throughout  the  United  States;  that  is,  full  freight  is  allowed  to 
every  wholesaler.  However  a  plumbing  contractor  who  is  located 
outside  a  recognized  "jobbing  center"  must  pay  freight  on  shipments 
from*the  wholesaler. 

Paint  materials — linseed  oil. — Linseed  oil  is  marketed  on  a  zone 
price  system  with  each  seller  maintaining  uniform  delivered  prices 
within  each  zone.  Zone  1,  comprising  the  North  Central  States 
including  Minnesota,  is  generally  the  base  zone  from  which  differentials 
to  other  zones  are  calculated.  The  position  of  this  zone  may  be 
explained  by  the  fact  that  Minnesota  is  the  largest  linseed  oil  producing 
State.  Delivered  prices  in  other  zones  rise  progressively  with  the 
smallest  advances  in  the  East  and  Northeastern  States,  and  the  largest 
advance  in  the  Pacific  and  Mountain  States.  Neither  base  prices  nor 
zone  differentials  are  the  same  for  all  sellers.  The  maximum  difter- 
ential  between  the  base  zone  and  zone  8  (the  area  last  described)  is 
0.6  cents  per  pound. 

Paint  materials — white  lead. — The  largest  companies  sell  through 
retail  dealers  on  a  consignment  basis,  thus  exercising  direct  control 
over  retail  prices.  Prices  vary  on  a  zone  basis.  Areas  nearest  ware- 
house or  manufacturing  points  are  "freight  free"  and  this  is  called  the 
"par  zone."  Beyond  this  area,  freight  charges  are  added  in  small 
increments;  thus  there  is  a  one-fourth-cent  zone,  a  one-half-cent  zone, 
etc.  It  is  understood  that  much  of  the  white  lead  sold  is  marketed  in 
the  "par  zone." 

Prepared  paints. — There  is  no  uniformity  of  geographic  pricing 
practice  in  the  sale  of  prepared  paints.  This  may  be  partly  due  to  the 
fact  that  there  are  material  quality  differences  between  the  product  of 
rival  producers  with  resultant  emphasis  upon  nonprice  competition. 

Several  of  the  larger  paint  manufacturers  who  distribute  on  a 
national  basis  use  a  4-zone  system.  Zone  1,  comprising  most  of  the 
Northeast,  is  the  base  zone;  prices  in  zone  2  range  from  4  cents  to  6 
cents  higher,  in  zone  3  from  8  cents  to  12  cents  higher,  and  in  zone  4 
from  13  cents  to  18  cents  higher.  In  each  zone  full  freight  is  allowed 
to  every  jobbing  center,  and  transportation  costs  from  these  jobbing 
centers  must  be  paid  by  the  purchaser. 

The  usual  practice  of  medium-sized  producers,  operating  on  a 
regional  basis,  is  to  quote  f.  o.  b.  destination  prices  or  f.  o.  b.  plant 
prices  with  full  freight  allowed  or  prepaid.  In  some  cases,  however, 
freight  will  not  be  allowed  on  shipments  of  less  than  a  hundred  pounds. 

Some  small  plants  with  limited  sales  areas  quote  a  straight  f.  o.  b. 
plant  price  and  make  no  attempt  to  equalize  delivered  costs. 

Of  29  companies  from  which  data  were  obtained,  7  operate  on  the 
multiple-zone  basis  with  freight  allowed  to  job  or  warehouse  points 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  315 

in  each  zone;  17  quote  an  f.  o.  b.  price  with  full  freight  allowed  to  every 
jobbing  destination,  and  5  quote  straight  f.  o.  b.  plant. 

Wiridow  glass. — Window  glass  is  sold  on  a  full  freight  equahzation 
basis.  The  basis  of  quotation  is  a  discount  from  a  published  list  price. 
The  latter  is  purely  nominal  and  changes  rarely,  modifications  in 
price  being  made  by  altering  discounts.  Thus  the  nominal  list  price 
was  unchanged  from  1913  to  1938.  There  are  two  list  prices  in  effect 
in  the  United  States,  one  applying  to  the  territory  east  of  the  Rockies 
and  the  other  to  the  west  coast.  It  is  said  that  the  west  .coast  differ- 
ential reflects  the  pressure  of  foreign  competition  in  that  area. 

Summary. — The  prevailing  geographic  price  structure  for  the  build- 
ing materials  which  have  been  described  are  summarized  below: 

Lime. — Full  freight  equalization. 

Cement. — Multiple  basing  points. 

Brick. — Purely  local,  with  uniform  prices,  delivered  to  job. 

Sand  and  gravel. — Local,  with  uniform  prices,  delivered  to  job. 

Building  tile. — Local,  with  uniform  prices,  delivered  to  job,  but 
shghtly  greater  radius  than  brick. 

Floor  tile. — Limited  freight  equalization. 

Sewer  pipe. — Limited  freight  equalization. 

Gypsum  plaster. — Full  freight  equalization. 
.    Insulation  board. — Uniform  delivered  price,  nation-wide. 

Prepared  roofing. — Limited  freight  equalization  from  pubUshed 
shipping  points. 

Heating  boilers  and  radiation. — F.  o.  b.  plant,  limited  freight  allow- 
ance. 

Plumbing  fixtures. — Full  freight  allowance,  uniform  delivered  prices, 
anywhere  in  the  United  States. 

Linseed  oil. — Zone  system,  with  uniform  delivered  prices  in  each 
zone. 

White  lead. — Uniform  delivered  zone  prices,  on  consignment. 

Prepared  paints. — 1.  Companies  selling  on  national  scale:  Uniform 
delivered  zone  prices.  2.  Companies  operating  in  limited  region: 
Full  freight  allowed.     3.  Small  plants:  F.  o.  b.  plant. 

Window  glass. — Full  freight  equahzation. 

FURNITURE    INDUSTRY 

There  are  two  major  divisions  of  the  furniture  industry — household 
furniture,  and  oflfice  furniture  and  fixtures.  In  1935,  according  to  the 
Census  of  Manufactures,  the  total  value  of  household  furniture  pro- 
duced was  $336,000,000,  of  which  $301,000,000  was  made  of  wood, 
$32,000,000  of  metal,  and  $3,000,000  of  fiber,  reed,  etc.  Office  furni- 
ture and  fixtures  were  considerably  less  important;  their  total  value 
was  $72,000,000,  of  which  $45,000,000  was  wood  and  fiber,  and 
$27,000,000  metal. ^"^  Household  furniture  is  usually  sold  on  a  straight 
f.  o.  b.  factor}^  basis,  while  business  furniture  is  quoted  on  a  zone 
basis. 

Household  furniture. — Household  furniture  is  sold  on  an  f.  o.  b. 
factory  basis  with  virtually  no  freight  allowance  or  equalization. 
The  principal  exceptions  follow: 

(1)  Prices  for  furniture  are  usually  "crated"  prices.  Sometimes, 
however,  furniture  is  shipped  by  private  or   contract   carrier  "un- 

•'  Bureau  of  Census,  Biennial  Census  of  Manufactures,  1935,  p.  456. 


316  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

crated."     In  the  latter  case,  the  manufacturer  frequently  assumes 
the  cost  of  shipping  up  to  50  or  100  miles  "in  lieu  of  crating." 

(2)  In  some  cases  the  buyer  may  not  wish  to  assume  title  until 
furniture  is  set  up.  In  such  cases  sales  may  be  on  a  contract  basis  and 
the  price  quoted  will  be  a  delivered  and  set-up  price. 

This  difference  applies  only  to  the  forna  of  quotation,  however, 
and  the  delivered  price  is  arrived  at  by  adding  shipping  and  handling 
costs  to  the  plant  price. 

(3)  Certain  minor  geographic  and  product  subdivisions  of  the  indus- 
try apparently  sell  their  products  on  the  basis  of  systematic  delivered 
pricing  practices,  involving  freight  absorption.  Some  of  the  largest 
furniture  producers  on  the  west  coast  quote  uniform  delivered  prices 
to  all  retailers  throughout  their  trading  area.  Cedar  chests,  a  special- 
ized item,  the  bulk  of  which  is  produced  by  four  large  mills  located 
in  different  sections  of  the  East,  are  sold  freight  equalized. 

(4)  There  is  occasional  sporadic  unsystematic  freight  absorption 
to  meet  special  competitive  conditions  or  in  order  to  make  a  desired 
sale. 

The  general  observance  of  uniform  plant  p^rices  occurs  despite  the 
fact  that  freight  is  by  no  means  a  negligible  element.  According  to 
Interstate  Commerce  Commission  figures,*^  the  ratio  of  freight 
revenue  to  value  at  destination  on  carload  shipments  of  furniture,  other 
than  metal,  during  1936  was  10.6  percent.  For  metal  furniture  this 
ratio  was  6.8  percent.  Presumably  the  ability  to  maintain  uniform 
plant  prices  reflects  the  fact  that  the  product  is  highly  differentiated 
so  that  competition. is  largely  on  a  nonprice  basis. 

Business  furniture. — Business  furniture  is  generally  sold  on  a  basis 
of  three  uniform  delivered  price  zones;  the  East,  the  Midwest,  and  the 
far  West.  In  general,  prices  in  the  far  western  and  middle  western 
zones  are  about  20  percent  and  10  percent,  respectively,  higher  than 
in  the  eastern  zone. 

These  relationships  may  be  partly  explained  by  the  fact  that  all 
manufacturers  doing  business  on  a  national  scale  are  located  in  the 
eastern  zone  which,  moreover,  accounts  for  about  70  percent  of  total 
consumption.  Presumably,  smaller  manufacturers  located  in  the 
Midwest  and  West  and  doing  business  on  a  regional  or  local  basis 
find  it  expedient  to  conform  generally  with  the  prices  set  by  their 
larger  rivals.  The  difference  in  structure  between  office  and  house- 
hold furniture  may  reflect  to  some  extent  the  fact  that  the  former  is  a 
more  standardized  product,  in  the  sale  of  which,  therefore,  price  is  a 
major  market  factor. 

CHEMICALS 

The  chemical  industry  includes  an  extremely  wide  variety  of 
products  sold  under  many  conditions  and  to  many  dift'erent  kinds  of 
buyers.  Competition  differs  widely  in  form  and  in  intensity  for  differ- 
ent products  and  in  different  markets.  Thus  the  price  structures  of 
some  chemicals  must  be  adjusted  to  meet  the  competition  of  imports; 
in  the  case  of  others,  substitute  products  offer  a  serious  problem.  For 
many  iterns  production  is  concentrated  in  a  narrow  geographic  area, 
for  others  it  is  widely  scattered. 

"Op.  cit..  p.  11. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER  317 

Under  such  circumstances,  it  is  only  natural  that  the  geographic 
price  structures  encountered  should  show  a  similar  diversity.  Differ- 
ences in  practice  appear  not  only  between  products  but  extend  also 
to  the  sales  of  the  same  products  under  different  forms  or  different 
conditions.  One  practice  may  be  followed  in  one  section  of  the  coun- 
try and  a  totally  dift'erent  one  in  another.  The  size  of  the  shipment 
is  important;  thus  there  are  variations  as  between  carload  and  1.  c.  1. 
lots.  Differences  may  be  introduced  by  the  method  of  packaging,  as 
between  products  sold  in  bulk,  tank  cars,  drums,  cylinders,  and  other 
kinds  of  containers.  For  example,  the  distribution  of  a  product  in 
cylinders  involves  problems  distinct  from  those  encountered  in  its 
shipment  in  drums  or  carboys,  since  transportation  costs  are  much 
higher  and  the  problem  of  returning  the  cylinder  and  often  of  servicing 
is  added. 

There  is,  moreover,  a  major  distinction  between  spot  and  contract 
markets.  The  bulk  of  heavy  chemicals,  such  as  sulfuric  acid  and  soda 
ash — 90  percent  or  more  in  the  case  of  many  important  products — 
moves  on  the  basis  of  contract  agreements.  According  to  some  mem- 
bers of  the  industry,  however,  both  price  and  geographic  structure  is 
the  same  for  many  products  for  contract  and  for  spot  sales,  the  only 
important  Hifferonce  being  that  contracts  guarantee  the  purchaser 
against  pr'^e  increases  for  the  period  specified.  However  contract 
prices  are  g  merally  materially  under  the  spot  market  for  most  chem- 
icals. 

Before  describing  the  extent  to  which  particular  types  of  geograph- 
ical price  practice  are  observed,  it  is  useful  to  consider  briefly  the 
pattern  of  variation  for  a  few  important  products,  in  order  to  indicate 
some  of  the  considerations  which  influence  the  choice  of  practice. 

One  product  whose  price  structure  is  quite  complex  is  carbon  black, 
production  of  which  is  concentrated  in  Texas.  About  95  percent  of 
carbon  black  is  sold  in  carload  lots.  The  buyer  may  purchase  either 
on  a  delivered  basis,  for  which  purpose  the  country  is  divided  into 
five  zones,  or  else  he  may  buy  f.  o.  b.  Gulf  ports.  On  November  13, 
1939,  for  example,  the  price  f.  o.  b.  Gulf  ports  for  delivery  in  North 
America  was  $0.0275  per  pound  for  the  standard  grade,  packed  in 
bags.  Zone  delivered  prices  varied  from  $0,031  per  pound  in  Texas 
and  adjoining  States  (Arkansas,  Colorado,  Kansas,  part  of  Missouri, 
and  New  Mexico)  to  $0.0375  in  the  most  distant  zone,  which  includes 
New  England,  the  Middle  Atlantic  States,  Virginia,  and  the  Carolinas. 
The  high  concentration  of  production  in  Texas  apparently  makes  it 
possible  to  maintain  this  zone  sj^stem  with  delivered  prices  increasing 
in  rough  approximation  to  the  distance  from  the  Texas  area. 

A  totally  different  structure  is  observed  in  the  case  of  1.  c.  I.  lots. 
Here  again  the  buyer  has  the  option  of  purchasing  on  a  delivered  or 
f.  o.  b.  basis.  The  f.  o.  b.  price  was  $0.0575  per  pound  on  November 
13,  1939,  or  substantially  above  the  carload  price.  On  f.  o.  b.  sales, 
freight  is  equalized  to  the  nearest  competing  plant.  However,  for  a 
premium  of  $0,005  per  pound,  that  is,  for  a  total  price  of  $0.0625  per 
pound,  the  product  is  delivered  anywhere  in  the  United  States.  This 
is  equivalent  to  a  freight  equalization  system  for  the  areas  immediately 
surrounding  producing  centers,  and  a  postage-stamp  system  through 
the  balance  of  the  country. 


318  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

In  the  case  of  industrial  benzol,  which  is  a  basic  coal  tar  product, 
the  structure  varies  both  with  the  quantity  shipped  and  the  type  of 
packaging.  The  great  bulk  (probably  99  percent)  of  industrial  benzol 
is  shipped  in  tank  cars.  Tank  car  shipments  east  of  Omaha  ar^sold 
on  an  f.  o.  b.  basis  with  full  freight  allowed;  that  is,  the  delivered 
price  is  uniform  throughout  the  entire  eastern  part  of  the  United  States 
where  the  bulk  of  the  product  is  manufactured.  When  the  destination 
is  Omaha  or  West,  a  basing  point  system  is  used,  with  prices  quoted 
f.  o.  b.  Minnequa,  Colo.,  at  which  point  an  important  plant  is  located. 
On  November  13,  1939,  the  f.  o.  b.  Minnequa  price  was  quoted  at  the 
same  level  as  the  freight-allowed  price  east  of  Omaha. 

Some  industrial  benzol  is  sold  in  drums,  obviously  a  more  expensive 
method  of  packaging  and  shipping.  Under  such  circumstances  freight 
is  not  allowed.  On  carload  lots,  however,  freight  is  equalized  to  the 
nearest  competing  plant,  while  on  1.  c.  1.  lots  there  is  no  equalization. 

In  the  case  of  these  two  products  alone,  therefore,  almost  every 
common  variety  of  geographic  structure  is  encountered.  A  simple 
f .  o.  b.  system  is  used  for  1,  c.  1.  shipments  of  benzol ;  prices  are  quoted 
f.  o.  b.  with  freight  equalized  for  carload  shipments  of  benzol  in  drums 
and  for  1.  c.  1.  shipments  of  carbon  black.  Carload  lots  of  carbon 
black  are  sold  on  a  zone  basis  and  the  eastern  part  of  the  country 
constitutes  a  single  zone  for  tank  cars  of  benzol.  A  postage-stamp 
system  applies  to  carbon  black  in  1.  c.  1.  lots  except  for  areas  adjacent 
to  producing  centers;  tank  cars  of  benzol  are  sold  in  the  West  on  a 
basing-point  system,  while  Gulf  ports  constitute  optional  basing  points 
for  carload  lots  of  carbon  blaclc. 

Because  of  the  vast  number  of  products  involved  and  the  complexity 
and  diversity  of  practices  encountered,  it  would  be  impractical  to 
attempt  to  present  a  comprehensive  analysis  of  price  structures  in  the 
chemical  industry  as  a  whole.  Instead,  a  limited  number  of  important 
and  representative  products  have  been  selected  as  illustrative.  Infor- 
mation regarding  the  practices  for  these  products  was  derived  in  part 
directly  from  the  members  of  the  industry  and  in  part  from  the  form 
of  price  quotation  in  the  Oil,  Paint  and  Drug  Reporter. 

Practically  all  of  these  products  are  standard  in  character  so  that 
it  is  almost  imperative  for  each  producer  to  meet  the  quotation  of 
more  advantageously  located  rivals  in  every  market  in  which  he 
wishes  to  sell.  Consequently  it  is  not  surprising  that  for  virtually 
every  product  regarding  which  information  was  obtained,  some  scheme 
for  equalizing  freight  or  otherwise  meeting  competitive  delivered 
prices  within  each  market  was  encountered. 

Simple  f.  0.  b.  plant  systems. — Simple  f .  o.  b.  plant  systems  with  no 
form  of  freight  allowance  are  uncommon  in  the  chemical  industry. 
They  are  encountered  primarily  in  the  case  of  small  lots  where  the 
amount  involved  in  the  transaction  is  not  large  enough  to  offer  the 
seller  any  incentive  to  absorb  freight  in  order  to  dispose  of  his  product. 
L.  c.  I.  lots  of  benzol  have  been  mentioned  as  an  example.  Another 
is  cellulose  acetate  in  quantities  of  less  than  100  pounds,  at  least  in 
the  case  of  some  producers. 

This  system  may  also  be  used  when  there  are  substantial  quality 
differences  between  products  produced  in  different  areas,  as  in  the 
case  of  phosphate  rock,  an  item  which  will  be  considered  under  the 
heading  of  fertilizer  materials. 

Freight  equalization  systems. — The  practice  most  commonly  en- 
countered in  the  limited  group  of  products  covered  is  simple  freight 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  319 

equalization  to  the  nearest  competing  plajit.  Usually  f.  0.  b.  prices 
at  each  mill  are  identical  or  nearly  so.  This  is  the  system  used,  for 
example,  in  the  case  of  sulfuric  acid  which  is  sold  f.  o.  b.  works, 
freight  equalized.  Manufacturers  report  that  the  same  practice  is 
followed  in  the  case  of  sodium  bichromate,  tribasic  calcium  phosphate, 
and  aluminum  sulfate.  Of  course,  the  manufacturer  may  simply 
decline  to  sell  "in  territory  so  remote  that  excessive  freight  absorption 
is  required. 

Frequently  this  form  of  freight  equalization  is  restricted  to  certain 
kinds  of  sales,  usually  to  carload  lots.  This  is  true,  for  example,  of 
soda  ash,  sodium  hydroxide,  sodium  silicate,  and  benzol  shipped  in 
drums. 

F.  o.  b.  pricing  with  freight  equalization  to  the  nearest  plant  is  also 
used  for  hydrochloric  acid,  anh3^drous  ammonia  in  tank  cars  only, 
sodium  bicarbonate,  calcium  carbide,  tribasic  sodium  phosphate  and 
nitrocellulose.  In  the  case  of  acetic  acid,  commercial  grade,  the  same 
system  is  used  except  in  States  on  the  eastern  seaboard  and  the 
Pacific  coast. 

Postage  stamp  and  zone  pricing. — Although  freight  equalization  to 
the  nearest  competitive  plant  seems  to  be  the  practice  most  commonly 
encountered  in  chemical  markets,  many  chemicals  are  sold  on  some 
basis  which  achieves  uniformity  of  delivered  prices  within  specified 
zones  or,  more  rarely,  throughout  the  United  States.  In  some  cases 
a  delivered  price  is  quoted  directly,  in  others  the  quotation  is  f.  o.  b. 
plant  but  freight  is  allowed  or  prepaid  by  the  seller. 

Among  products  which  are  apparently  sold  on  the  basis  of  uniform 
delivered  prices  throughout  the  United  States  are  cellulose  acetate  in 
quantities  of  100  pounds  or  more,  and  butyl  acetate  in  drums  or  tanks. 
For  the  first  of  these  the  delivered  price  is  quoted  directly,  for  the 
other  two  the  price  is  f.  o.  b.  plant  with  full  freight  allowed.  Postage- 
stamp  systems  are  also  common  in  the  case  of  coal-tar  dyes,  which  are 
usually  shipped  in  1.  c.  1.  lots. 

A  practice  intermediate  between  freight  equalization  and  delivered 
price  uniformity  has  been  already  described  in  the  case  of  carbon 
black,  sold  in  1.  c.  1.  lots.*^ 

For  most  chemicals  sold  on  a  delivered  price  or  freight  allowed  basis, 
zone  systems  rather  than  postage-stamp  systems  are  observed.  This 
may  be  due  to  the  fact  that  freight  constitutes  a  relatively  important 
element  in  the  price  of  many  of  these  products  and  the  major  centers 
of  production  and  consumption  are  often  concentrated  so  that  it  is 
not  considered  desirable  to  ship  to  minor  remote  markets  at  the  same 
rate  as  to  more  fortunately  located  users.  In  some  cases,  moreover, 
the  existence  of  foreign  competition  makes  it  necessary  to  treat  sea- 
board areas  on  a  special  basis. 

For  example,  acetic  acid  is  sold  at  a  uniform  delivered  price  in 
Atlantic  Seaboard  States  (in  contiast  with  the  practice  of  freight 
equalization  used  elsewhere).  Benzol  in  tank  cars  (by  far  the  most 
important  means  of  shipment)  is  sold  freight  allowed  to  points  east  of 
Omaha.  Although  for  normal  butyl  acetate  freight  is  allowed  any- 
where in  the  United  States,  secondary  butyl  acetate  **  is  sold  on  this 
basis  only  east  of  the  Mississippi  River,  possibly  because  its  price  per 
pound  is  lower  so  that  freight  becomes  a  relatively  larger  item.  Carbon 
black  in  carload  quantities  is  quoted  on  a  delivered  basis  with  prices 

"  It  is  understood  that  less  than  5  percent  of  carbon  black  is  sold  In  1.  c.  1.  lots. 

♦*  Normal  and  secondary  butyl  acetate  are  different  chemicals;  not  merely  different  grades  of  the  same 
chemical. 


320  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

varying  for  five  zones.  There  are  four  zones  for  synthetic  methyl 
alcohol.  In  the  case  of  carbon  tetrachloride,  four  zones  are  observed' 
both  for  carload  and  1.  c.  1.  quantities,  but  in  zone  4  (Pacific  and  Moun- 
tain States)  the  price  is  f.  o.  b.  cars  at  specified  Pacific  ports  (Los 
Angeles,  San  Francisco,  Portland,  Seattle).  Zone  systems  are  also 
used  for  1.  c.  1.  shipments  only  of  caustic  soda  and  soda  ash.  On  June 
7,  1940,  a  leading  producer  of  flake  calcium  chloride  started  quoting 
prices  for  that  chemical  on  the  basis  of  a  zone  sj^stem, involving  10 
zones  and  3  subzonos.  This  superseded  a  postage  stamp  system  which 
had  been  previously  observed. 

The  zone  system  for  anhydrous  ammonia  in  cylinders  is  in  some 
aspects  a  special  case.  There  are  two  sets  of  prices  quoted  for  this 
product  by  a  major  producer.  One  of  these  is  a  series  of  State-wide 
delivered  prices  for  practically  every  State  in  the  Union  for  delivery 
from  base  points  only,  located  in  Philadelphia,  St.  Louis,  New  York, 
Newark,  Niagara  Falls,  Detroit,  Chicago,  and  Boston.  In  addition 
there  are  stock-point  prices  within  various  States  or  areas  for  deliveries 
from  stock;  these  latter  prices  apply  to  particular  cities  only.  There 
are  also  a  number  of  zone  systems  for  delivery  from  stock  points  in 
addition  to  the  State-wide  delivered  price  zones  previously  mentioned. 
The  reason  for  this  price  structure  is  probably  the  fact  that  the  use  of 
cylinders  in  the  distribution  of  the  product  entails  very  heavy  trans- 
portation costs  both  in  outgoing  and  incoming  shipments  of  the  cylin- 
ders. In  addition  a  certain  amount  of  servicing  is  necessary.  As  a 
result,  zones  for  this  product  are  smaller  in  size  and  much  greater  in 
number  than  for  most  of  the  other  products  described. 

Zone  dijfe?mtials  and  changes  in  zone  systems. — The  uniformity 
with  which  zone  boundaries  and  price  differentials  are  maintained 
over  a  period  of  time  is  significant  in  interpreting  the  significance 
of  zone  systems.  Consequently  an  analysis  has  been  prepared  of 
zone  relationships  since  July  193G  for  four  chemicals;  caustic  soda 
(1.  c.  1.),  soda  ash  (1.  c  1.),  synthetic  methanol  (1.  c.  1.)  and  carbon 
black  (standard,  carloads).     This  is  presented  in  table  2. 

It  is  evident  that  for  some  of  these  products  zone  relationships  are 
more  persistent  than  for  others.  Zone  price  differejitials  have  remained 
unchanged  since  July  1936  for  1.  c.  1.  shipments  of  caustic  soda  and  soda 
ash.  In  the  case  of  synthetic  methanol,  prices  and  price  relationsliip 
between  zones  w^ere  changed  nationally  between  July  1936  and  July 
1937  and  then  remained  uniform  till  April  1940.  Prices  of  carbon 
black  were  drastically  revised  between  July  1937  and  July  1938  and 
the  revision  involved  some  change  in  zone  difi'erentials.  In  general 
there  seems  to  have  been  no  tendency  to  change  zone  boundaries  as 
such  during  the  period  covered,  but  in  several  instances  zones  have 
been  merged  since  1936.  Thus  all  Northeastern  States  were  combined 
into  a  single  zone  for  the  caustic  soda  and  soda  ash  markets  between 
July  1936  and  July  1937,  while  New  Mexico,  Texas,  and  Wyoming, 
which  constituted  a  separate  zone  for  methanol  during  1936,  were 
quoted  on  the  same  basis  as  other  Mountain  and  Southern  States  by 
1937.  If  this  small  group  is  representative  there  seems  to  be  a  general 
tendency  for  zone  relationships  in  chemical  markets  to  persist  over  a 
period  of  time,  but  modifications  to  meet  changing  conditions  do  occur. 

Basing-poiiU  systems. — Basing-point  systems  as  such  are  apparently 
uncommon  in  chemical  markets.     Examples  already  referred  to  are 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


321 


benzol  in  tank  carlo ts  which  is  quoted  f.  o.  b.  Minnequa,  Colo.,  for 
delivery  at  Omaha  and  West;  carbon  black  which  can  be  purchased 
f.  o.  b.  Gulf  ports  at  the  buyer's  option,  and  carbon  tetrachloride  which 
is  quoted  f.  o.  b.  Pacific  ports  for  dehvery  in  Pacific  and  Mountain 
States, 

Summary. — It  is  clear  that  the  geographic  price  structure  of  the 
chemical  industry  falls  into  no  simple  pattern  and  that  practices  often 
show  wide  variation  for  a  single  product  sold  under  somewhat  different 
terms.  For  convenience  in  reference  the  geographic  structures  prevail- 
ing for  the  products  discussed  are  summarized  in  table  1. 

The  reasons  for  the  establishment  of  particular  types  of  geographic 
price  structure  for  individual  products  under  specific  conditions  are 
difficult  to  trace.  Undoubtedly  many  factors  enter,  including  the 
historical  development  of  the  industry  and  its  present  competitive 
conditions,  the  relative  importance  of  the  cost  of  freight,  etc.  If  any 
generalization  is  possible,  it  may  be  that  simple  freight  equalization  is 
most  common  in  the  case  of  heavy  chemicals,  for  which  transportation 
costs  bulk  importantly,  while  delivered  or  zone  systems  are  more  likely 
to  occur  where  freight  is  a  less  important  factor.  Thus,  such  basic 
chemicals  as  sulfuric  acid,  soda  ash,  sodium  bicarbonate,  and  hydro- 
chloric acid  are  all  sold  on  a  freight-equalized  basis,  while  products 
which  cost  more  per  pound,  such  as  cellidose,  butyl  acetate,  and  coal- 
tar  dyes  are  sold  on  a  delivered  basis.  On  the  other  hand,  this  is  far 
from  an  invariable  rule  and  many  of  the  more  expensive  products  are 
also  sold  on  an  f.  o.  b.  plant,  freight-equalized  basis. 

Table  1. — Geographic  'price  structures  for  selected  chemicals,  summarized 


Product 

F.  0.  b. 
plant— No 
equaliza- 
tion 

F.  0.  b. 

plant- 
freight 
equalized 

Uniform 

delivered 

prices 

Zone  system 

Basing-point 
system 

X        

X 

Soda  ash     

Carloads 

L.c.l 

L.c.l 

L.c.l - 

Sodium  hvdroxide 

Carloads 

Sodium  silicate 

Carloads 

X           .     .. 

X 

Sodium  bichromate 

X 

Calcium  phosphate  (tribasic) 

X 

Calcium  carbide           .  . 

X 

Calcium  chloride  (flake)..- 

X     . 

Aluminum  sulfate 

X 

Anhydrous  ammonia 

Tank  cars 

Cylinders  .. 
Seaboard 
States. 

Acetic  acid 

Except  sea- 
board 
States. 

Cans 

Butyl  acetate  (normal) 

Drums    or 
tanks. 

East  of  the 
Missis- 
sippi. 

100    pounds 
or  more. 

Butyl  acetate  (secondary) 

Cellulose  acetate.. 

Loss    than 
100  pounds. 

Synthetic  methyl  alcohol 

X     

Carbon  tetrachloride 

Except   I'a- 
cific    and 
Mountain 
States. 

Carload  lots. 

Pacific     and 

Carbon  black . 

L.c.l.  (buy- 
er's   op- 
tion). 

X 

L.c.l.  (buy- 
er's   op- 
tion). 

Mountain 
States. 

Carload  lots 

Nitrocellulose  ... 

(alterna- 
tive). 

Benzol 

Drums— 
l.c.l. 

Drums- 
carlots. 

Tank     cars 
(east    of 
Omaha). 

X        

Tank    cars 

Coal-tar  dyes. 

(Omaha 
and  West). 

1 

322 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EKIONOMIC  POWER 


Table  2. — Zone  prices  and  zone  differentidls — Selected  chemicals 

CAUSTIC  SODA,  FLAKE,  DJRUMS,  L.  C.  L.,  PER  100  POUNDS 


Delivered  prices 

Differentials  from  zone  1 

Zone 

July  27, 
1936 

July  26, 
1937 

July  25, 
1938 

Nov.  17, 
1939 

July  27, 
1936 

July  26, 
1937 

July  25, 
1938 

Nov.  13, 
1939 

1 

$4.00 
4.05 
4.15 
4.40 
4.80 
4.05 

$3.45 

3.55 

$3.55 

la 

$0.05 
.15 
.40 
.80 
.05 

2 

3 

3.60 
3.S5 
4.25 

3.70 
3.95 
4.35 

3.70 
3.95 
4.35 

$0.15 
.40 
.80 

$0.15 
.40 
.80 

.$0. 15 
.40 

4 

.80 

5         .   -.•..- 

SODA  ASH,  DENSE,  58  PERCENT,  BARRELS.  L.  C.  L.,  PER  100  POUNDS 


1  . 

$2.37 
2.42 
2.52 
2.77 
3.17 
2.47 

•    $2.25 

$2.35 

.      $2. 35 

la 

$0.05 
.15. 
.40 
.80 
.10 

2           

2.40 
2.65 
3.05 

2.50 
2.75 
3.15 

2.50 
2.75 
3.15 

$0.15 
.40 
.80 

..$0.15 
.40 
.80 

$0.15 

3   

.40 

4 ^.... 

.80 

5 

ZONE  LIMITS  FOR  CAUSTIC  SODA  AND  SODA  ASH 

Zone  /.—East  of  Mississippi  River,  but  including  Davenport,  Iowa,  and  St.  Louis,  Mo.,  to  south  bound- 
ary rtf  Vircinia  and  Kentucky. 

Zone  la.— New  England  (combined  with  zone  1  after  193R). 

Zone  '.—  Alabama,  Florida,  Georgia,  Iowa  (except  Davenport),  east  Kansas  (including  Wichita),  Minne- 
sota, Mississippi.  Missouri  (except  St.  Louis),  North  Carolina,  Omaha,  South  Carrlina,  and  Tennessee. 

Zonf  -S — .Arkansas,  Kansas  (west  of  Wichita),  Louisiana,  Nebraska  (except  Omaha),  North  Dakota, 
Oklahoma,  South  Dakota,  Texas  (exceprt  EI  Paso). 

Zonr  4-— Arizona,  Colorado,  El  Paso,  Idaho,  Montana,  Nevada,  New  Mexico,  Spokane,  Utah,  Wyoming. 

Zone  6.— California,  Oregon,  Washington  (except  Spokane). 


METHANOL 

SYNTHETIC,  DRUMS,  L. 

C.  L.,  PER  GALLON 

^one 

Delivered  prices 

Differentials  from  zone  1 

5 

July  27, 
1936 

July  26, 
1937 

July  25, 
1938 

Nov.  13, 
1939 

July  27, 
1936 

July  26, 
1937 

July  25, 
1938 

Nov.  13, 
1939 

1 

$0.  425 
.470 
.455 
.610 
.520 

$0.  405 
.470 
.445 
.600 

$0.  405 
.470 
.445 
.600 

$0. 405 
.470 
.445 
.600 

2 

$0,045 
.030 
.185. 
.095 

$0.  065 
.040 
.195 

$0.  065 
.040 
.195 

$0. 065 

3 

.040 

4 

.195 

5 

ZONE  UMITS  FOR  SYNTHETIC  METHANOL 

Zone  /.—Connecticut,  Delaware,  District  of  Columbia,  Illinois,  Indiana,  Iowa,  Kentucky,  Maine,  Mary- 
land, Massachusetts,  Michigan,  Minnesota,  Missouri,  New  Hampshire,  New  Jersey,  New  York,  North 
Carolina,  Ohio,  Pennsylvania,  Rhode  Island,  Tennessee.  Vermont,  Virginia,  West  Virginia,  Wisconsin. 

Zone  2.— Alabama,  Arkansas,  Colorado,  Florida,  Georgia,  Kansas,  Louisiana,  Mississippi,  Nebraska, 
North  Dakota,  Oklahoma.  South  Carolina.  South  Dakota;  after  lvi36  Texas  and  Wyoming  included. 

Zone  S.— Los  Ansreles  and  San  Francisco,  Calif.;  Portland,  Oreg.;  Seattle,  Wash. 

Zone  4  —Arizona.  California  (except  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco),  Montana,  Nevada,  Idaho,  Oregon 
(except  Portlan.I),  Utah,  Washington  (except  Seattlel:  New  Mexico,  included  after  1930. 

Zone  5. —New  Mexico,  Texas,  Wyoming  for  1936  only. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


323 


Table  2. — Zone  prices  and  zone  differentials — Selected  chemicals — Continued 
CARBON  BLACK,  STANDARD.  BAGS,  PER- POUND,  C.  L. 


Delivered  prices 

Difierentials  from  zone 

A 

Zone 

July  27, 
1936 

July  26, 
1937 

July  25, 
1938 

Nov.  13, 
1939 

July  27, 
1936 

July  26, 
1937 

July  25, 
1938 

Nov.  13, 
1939 

A .-- -  - 

$0.  0445 
.0475 
.0605 
.0490 
.0505 
.0535 
.0530 

.0700 
.0750 

.0825 

$0. 0445 
.  0475 
.0505 
.  0490 
.0505 
.  05:'.5 
.0455 

.0700 
.0750 

.  os:.o 

$0. 0275 
.0310 
.0335 
.0325 
.0341 
.0375 
.0300 

.0575 
.0625 

.0700 

$0. 0275 
.0310 
.0335 
.0325 
.0341 
.0375 
.0300 

.0575 
.0025 

.0700 

B  -- 

$0.  0030 
.  OORO 
.0045 
.  0060 
.  0090 
.0085 

.  0255 
.0305 

.  0380 

$0. 0030 
.0060 
.0045 
.0060 
.  OO'JO 

.oo;o 

.0255 
.0305 

.0380 

$0.  0035 
.0060 
.0050 
.  0066 
.OiOO 
.0025 

.0300 
.0350 

0425 

$0.  0035 

c 

0060 

D     

.0050 

E   - 

.0066 

F   -- 

0100 

G ...- 

L.  c  1.  f.  0.  b.  whole- 
sale   

.0025 
.0300 

L.  c.  1  delivered 

Gartens  1.  r.  1.  de- 
livered  

.0350 
.  042.") 

ZONE   LIMITS  FOB  CARBON  BLACK 

Zone /I.— Delivered  rnil  (Gulf  ports)  for  delivery  in  North  America  (water  freights  extra) 

Zone  B. — Arkansas.  Colorado,  Kansas,  part  of  Missouri,  New  Mexico,  Te.xas  (except  coastal  ports). 

Zone  C— P-iciflt  Coa«t  States. 

Zone  /).— Illinois,  Iowa,  Wisconsin. 

Zone  E. — Florida,  Oeoreia,  Indiana,  Kentucky.  Michigan,  part  of  New  York,  Ohio,  part  of  Pennsyl- 
vania. Tennessee,  West  Vrpini  . 

Zone  F.— Maine,  Maryland.  Massachusetts.  New  Hampshire,  New  Jersey,  part  of  New  York,  North 
Carolina,  part  of  Pennsylvania,  Rhode  Island,  South  Carolina,  Vermont,  Virrinia. 

Zone  G.— Mexico  (f.  o.  b.  border  1938-30). 

Source:  Oil,  Paint  and  Drug  ReP'-rter. 


DRUGS,    COSMETICS,    AND    TOILETRIES 

Most  cosmetics,  toiletries,  and  proprietary  drugs  are  sold  at  uniform 
delivered  prices  throug-hout  the  United  States.  In  some  cases  the 
price  is  quoted  directly  on  a  delivered  basis;  in  others  freight  may  be 
allowed  or  be  prepaid.  Wliile  this  is  the  general  practice,  it  is  not 
universal,  the  most  common  variant  being  the  provision  that  the  seller 
will  pay  freight  only  on  shipments  of  a  specified  minimum  quantity. 
Thus  one  toothpaste  manufacturer  prepays  freight  only  on  lots  of  one 
gross  or  over,  while  one  seller  of  proprietary  medicines  sets  the  mini- 
mum limit  at  orders  of  at  least  $70. 

This  form  of  price  structure  reflects  a  number  of  characteristics 
common  to  the  market  for  most  of  these  products.  In  the  first  place, 
the  cost  of  transportation  is  rarely  more  than  an  insignificant  element 
in  the  price  of  the  delivered  product.  In  fact,  for  many  of  these  items 
costs  of  promotion  such  as  advertising  so  far  outweigh  the  physical 
costs  of  manufacture  and  shipment  that  the  latter  can  readily  be 
ignored  by  the  seller. 

Moreover,  minimum  resale  prices  both  at  retail  and  at  wholesale 
have  been  established  for  many  of  these  products  under  the  provisions 
of  the  so-called  fair  trade  laws  in  the  44  States  having  such  statutes. 
Prices  to  distributors  are  usualh'  related  to  retail  list  prices  by  a  system 
of  discounts.  Distributors  are  well  organized  and, have  been  vigilant 
in  protecting  or  expanding  their  sales  margins.  Consequently,  resent- 
ment might  be  aroused  on  the  part  of  distributors  remote  from  tJie 
seller's  plant  or  warehouse  if  they  were  called  upon  to  pay  freight  and 
thereby  found  their  margin  reduced  below  that  of  more  favorably 
located  wholesalers  or  retailers. 


324  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

In  addition,  many  of  the  larger  manufacturers  maintain  warehouses 
throughout  the  country,  while  some  distribute  to  retailers  through  del 
credere  agents  in  order  to  retain  control  over  prices  paid  by  retailers. 
In  these  circumstances  the  adoption  of  a  system  of  uniform  delivered 
prices  has  the  merit  of  simplicity  and  it  has  become  the  general  prac- 
tice. 

In  the  case  of  merchandise  not  bearing  an  advertised  trade-mark, 
the  same  practice  is  commonly  followed,  although  there  is  probably 
greater  tendency  to  use  f.  o.  b.  pricing  in  some  instances.  This  is 
particularly  true  in  the  case  of  standard  unbranded  drugs  and  chem- 
icals such  as  cocaine,  dextrose,  ether,  etc.  These  are  quoted  in  the 
Druggists  Circular,  a  standard  trade  periodical,  on  the  following  basis: 

These  prices  are  average  prices  for  quantities  retail  druggists  usually  buy. 
They  are  f.  o.  b.  New  York  or  St.  Louis,  and  are  subject  to  market  fluctuations. 
Retailers  at  points  distantly  located  from  market  centers  may  expect  to  pay 
jobbers  an  advance  over  the  quoted  prices  to  cover  transportation  costs. 

FERTILIZER    AND    FERTILIZER    MATERIALS 

The  price  structure  of  fertilizer  and  fertilizer  materials  is  extremely 
complex,  as  regards  both  geographic  differentials  and  other  terms  and 
conditions  of  sale.  Some  of  the  types  of  price  variation  are  described 
in  a  report  by  the  National  Resources  Committee. ^^ 

Freight  constitutes  a  fairly  important  element  in  price;  on  rail 
shipments  in  1936  freight  revenue  averaged  13  percent  of  delivered 
value  at  destination. ***  Producing  facilities,  at  least  for  mixed 
fertilizer,  are  scattered  and,  although  more  fertilizer  is  used  in  the 
southeastern  States  than  anywhere  else  in  the  United  States,  fertilizer 
is  sold  all  over  the  country.  Since  brand  names  are  not  particularly 
important,  any  differences  in  delivered  price  would  yield  a  significant 
local  competitive  advantage.  Consequently  an  extremely  detailed 
structure  for  eliminating  freight  as  a  competitive  element  has  developed 
in  the  industry. 

Insofar  as  sales  to  farm  users  are  involved,  the  basic  feature  of  this 
structure  is  a  zone  system,  but  it  is  subject  to  many  modifications, 
which  will  be  described  below.  Some  fertilizer  materials,  however, 
particularly  when  shipped  in  carload  lots  to  fertilizer  manufacturers 
or  mixers,  are  quoted  on  an  f.  o.  b.  or  basing  point  system. 

Fertilizer  materials. — Fertilizer  contains  three  basic  ingredients — 
nitrogen,  phosphorus,  and  potassium.  These  essential  elements  can 
be  supplied  by  a  number  of  different  chemicals,  which  can  either  be 
purchased  by  the  farmer  separately  or  in  prepared  mixtures  suitable 
to  the  requirements  of  his  soil  and  crops.  However,  some  raw- 
materials,  such  as  phosphate  rock,  are  not  in  form  suitable  for  direct 
use  and  must  be  processed  further  in  order  to  render  the  essential 
element  available  for  the  soil. 

When  farmers  purchase  fertilizer  materials  directly  in  less-than- 
carload  quantities,  the  price  structure  is  generally  similar  to  that  for 
mixed  fertilizer,  described  below.  On  sales  of  these  materials  to 
fertilizer  manufacturers,  or  to  users  in  straight  carload  lots,  geographic 
pricing  practices  vary  with  the  product.     Since  it  is  impractical  to 

.     «»  National  Resources  Committee,  Structure  of  the  Americr.n  Economy,  pt.  I,  pp.  175-176. 
<"  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  op.  cit. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  325 

describe  the  geographic  structure  for  each  material  in  common  use,  a 
few  of  the  more  important  will  be  presented  as  illustrations. 

The  first  basic  ingredient  of  fertilizer  is  nitrogen.  One  common 
source  of  this  element  is  ammonium  sulphate,  about  one-fifth  of  which 
is  imported;  the  balance  is  produced  in  domestic  ovens.  Despite  the 
relatively  small  proportion  supplied  from  outside  sources,  the  price 
structure  apparently  reveals  the  effect  of  this  competition.  Prices 
are  quoted  either  f.  o.  b.  Atlantic  or  Gulf  ports,  or  f.  o.  b.  cars  at  the 
nearest  inland  producing  oven  with  inland  prices  regularly  $1  below 
prices  at  the  ports.  Freight  is  equalized  so  that  the  buyer  pays  the 
lowest  combination  of  port  or  plant  price  and  freight  to  destination. 

An  important  alternative  source  of  nitrogen  is  cyanamid,  but  the 
amount  of  cyanamid  that  can  be  used  in  a  mixed  fertilizer  is  limited 
by  technical  considerations.  The  great  bulk  of  this  product  is  manu- 
factured in  Niagara  Falls,  Ontario.  Price  quotations  in  the  United 
States  are  on  a  uniform  delivered  basis.  The  reason  for  this  form  of 
quotation  is  uncertain,  but  it  may  be  because  cyanamid  must  always 
face  the  competition  of  other  nitrogen  carriers  and  the  uniform  price 
permits  itr  to  compete  over  a  wider  area  than  would  otherwise  be 
possible. 

The  primary  original  source  of  the  second  basic  fertilizer  ingredi- 
ent— phosphorus — is  phosphate  rock.  There  are  two  major  sources 
of  thiB  product,  Tennessee  and  Florida.  Apparently  the  Tennessee 
product  is  somewhat  superior  in  purity  to  that  in  Florida,  but  its  cost 
of  extraction  is  materially  greater.  Consequently,  the  Tennessee  pro- 
ducers make  little  effort  to  compete  with  the  Florida  pebble  in  most 
markets  but  confine  their  sales  to  superphosphate  producers  located 
in  Tennessee.  Selling  to  this  restricted  market,  there  is  no  need  for 
freight  equalization  and  they  can  operate  on  a  straight  f.  o.  b.  basis. 

The  Florida  pebble  mines  are  themselves  located  within  a  fairly 
narrow  geographical  area,  and  most  of  the  product  is  shipped  north 
by  boat.  Variations  in  the  locations  of  individual  mines  do  not  affect 
freight  charges  appreciably  and  can  be  ignored.  As  a  result  there 
seems  to  be  no  pressure  for  any  form  of  freight  equalization,  and  prices 
are  quoted  on  a  straight  f.  o.  b.  basis. 

In  order  to  be  rendered  available  as  plant  food,  the  phosphate  rock 
must  be  transformed  into  superphosphate.  A  large  proportion  of 
superphosphate  is  produced  in  Baltimore,  and  published  quotations 
are  usually  f.  o.  b.  that  city.  However,  there  are  many  superphos- 
phate plants  in  other  areas,  as  in  Tennessee,  which  also  quote  f.  o.  b. 
their  own  plants  with  an  effort  to  equalize  freight. 

The  third  primary  element — potassium — can  be  supplied  by  muriate 
of  potash.  There  are  two  primary  domestic  sources  of  this  product, 
New  Mexico  and  California.  However,  the  price  structure  has  been 
governed  not  by  the  domestic  product  but  by  foreign  imports  arriving 
at  Atlantic,  Gulf,  and  Pacific  ports.  Moreover,  a  substantial  portion 
of  the  domestic  product  is  also  shipped  by  water,  either  through  the 
Panama  Canal  from  California  or  via  the  Gulf  from  New  Mexico. 
As  a  result  the  price  has  been  quoted  c.  i.  f.  ports  plus  freight  to  the 
inland  destination.  There  are  40  ports  which  are  recognized  as  basing 
points,  and  the  base  price  at  each  is  the  same.  This  is  true  even 
though  much  domestic  potash  is  shipped  from  Carlsbad,  N.  Mex., 


326  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

or  Trona,  Calif,  at  a  freight  rate  entirely  unrelated  to  the  rate  which 
determines  the  price  structure.  While  this  is  equivalent  to  f.  o.  b. 
pricing  for  the  foreign  product,  it  has  all  the  characteristics  of  a  basing 
point  system  insofar  as  domestic  potash  is  concerned.  As  a  result 
it  is  estimated  that  buyers  in  the  Mississippi  and  Ohio  Valleys  pay 
several  dollars  a  ton  more  for  potash  under  the  port  basing  system 
than  they  would  pay  f.  o.  b.  Carlsbad  plus  freight  to  destination. 

This  method  of  quoting  prices  for  potash  has  recently  been  the 
subject  of  investigation  by  the  Department  of  Justice  and  the  Depart- 
ment of  Commerce.  During  May  1940  the  latter  agency  issued  a 
report  embodying  the  results  of  its  analysis.  Recommendations 
included  the  recognition  of  domestic  producing  centers  as  f.  o.  b. 
pricing  points,  and  the  establishment  of  a  fixed  differential  between 
prices  f.  o.  b.  these  producing  points  and  c.  i.  f.  port  prices. ^'^ 

Mixed  fertilizer. — Companies  selling  mixed  fertilizer  use  two  pri- 
mary methods  of  distribution,  dealers  and  agents.  In  recent  years 
there  has  been  a  marked  tendencj'^  to  abandon  the  use  of  independent 
dealers  in  favor  of  the  agency  relationship,  largely  because  the  latter 
permits  direct  control  over  resale  prices  by  the  producer.  Conse- 
quently, manufacturers  are  in  a  position  to  determine  the  delivered 
price  structure  to  farmers  directly.  Large  companies  issue  detailed 
price  lists  for  the  guidance  of  their  agents  (or  dealers),  which  indicate 
precisely  how  transportation  charges  are  to  be  treated. 

For  the  purposes  of  the  fertilizer  market,  the  United  States  is 
divided  into  some  19  zones  or  districts  which  are,  in  turn,  subdivided 
into  many  subzones.  These  subzones  may  themselves  be  split  into 
minor  divisions. 

Not  only  the  prices,  but  also  the  products  ofi'ered  for  sale,  vary 
between  these  different  areas.  The  ingredients  of  mixed  fertilizer 
must  be  adjusted  to  the  type  of  soil  and  the  crop,  and  in  addition 
state  regulations  may  prescribe  the  composition  of  the  product  which 
may  be  marketed  within  the  state.  Thus  most  of  the  mixes  offered 
for  sale  in  South  Carolina  are  quite  different  from  those  offered  in 
Ohio,  though  a  few  may  be  identical  in  both  areas. 

Conditions  of  sale  vary  to  some  extent  between  areas,  but  the  basic 
structure  is  similar.  In  each  zone  or  subzone  there  is  a  basic  price 
quotation  for  each  mix  which  applies  to  delivery  at  any  factory  or 
company  controlled  distributing  warehouse,  or  at  any  railroad  station 
or  boat  landing,  within  the  designated  area.  A  standard  trucking 
allowance  of  75  cents  per  ton  is  granted  to  cover  hauling  expenses 
to  the  farm.  However,  this  is  not  equivalent  in  practice  to  a  uniform 
delivered  price  within  the  zone  because  it  is  subject  to  many  stated 
exceptions. ^^ 

In  the  first  place  the  basic  quotation  is  for  delivery  at  buyer's 
railroad  station  or  boat  landing  only  in  carload  lots,  unless  there  is 
an  agent's  warehouse  at  such  station  or  landing  in  which  case  the 
price  applies  to  any  quantity.  Otherwise,  on  1.  c.  1.  lots,  the  customer 
must  pay  an  added  amount  equal  to  the  difference  between  the  carload 
and  1.  c.  1.  rates  from  the  nearest  designated  distributing  point. 

"  The  Potash  Industry,  a  report  submitted  to  the  Department  of  Justice  by  the  Department  of  Com- 
merce, prepared  by  Willard  L.  Thorp  and  Ernest  A.  Tupper,  May  1,  ]940. 

<'  Of  course  the  quotation  is  also  suliject  to  numerous  terms  related  to  factors  other  than  geographic 
such  as  time  of  payment,  method  of  packing,  etc.,  but  these  do  not  pertain  to  the  subject  under  di.scu'=sion 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  327 

Moreover  the  customer  can,  if  he  chooses,  accept  delivery  at  a 
plant  or  company  warehouse.  Under  such  circumstances  he  is 
granted  a  trucking  allowance  which  varies  with  the  length  of  haul 
to  his  farm.  In  some  areas  detailed  schedules  indicate  the  exact 
allowance  per  ton  based  upon  the  actual  shortest  Irighway  mileage, 
ranging  from  a  mimimum  allowiince  of  75  cents  up  to  and  including 
40  miles,  to  a  maximum  of  $4.70  for  400  miles.  In  other  areas  the 
trucking  allowance  is  determined  by  the  actual  carload  rate  of  freight 
from  factory  to  consumer's  nearest  railroad  delivery  point.  At 
times,  various  combinations  of  these  principles  are  followed. 

In  some  areas  there  are  further  modifications  designed  to  benefit 
consumers  who  happen  to  be  advantageously  located  with  respect 
to  certain  ports.  For  example,  in  the  South  Carolina  area,  if  the 
carload  freight  from  Wilmington  (N.  C),  Charleston  (S.  C),  or 
Savannah  (Ga.)  to  destination  is  less  than  $3.50  per  ton,  the  difference 
between  the  published  freight  rate  from  these  ports  and  $3.50  is 
deducted  from  the  list  price  for  the  zone. 

Apparently  this  price  structure  can  be  resolved  into  the  following 
elements: 

(1)  On  carload  shipments  the  price  is  f.  o.  b.  port  until  the  freight 
ratfe  reaches  a  prescribed  limit,  beyond  which  point  freight  is  absorbed 
by  the  seller  throughout  the  balance  of  the  zone  or  district. 

(2)  On  1.  c.  1.  shipments  the  company  will  absorb  only  the  carload 
rate  and  the  buyer  mu'st  pay  the  difference  between  that  and  the  rate 
actually  paid. 

(3)  The  buyer  has  the  option  of  accepting  delivery  at  plant  or 
warehouse,  and  receiving  a  trucking  allowance  which  is  related  to  the 
carload  freight  rate  or  to  the  highway  mileage. 

(4)  In  all  cases  a  fixed  discount  of  75  cents  is  applicable  as  an 
allowance  for  trucking  from  railroad  station  or  landing  to  farm. 
Since  this  allowance  is  apparently  granted  on  all  transactions,  it  does 
not,  strictly  speaking,  constitute  an  element  of  the  geographic  struc- 
ture but  is  equivalent  to  a  simple  standard  discount  off  list. 

In  general,  the  price  structure  applicable  to  sales  of  fertilizer 
materials  by  fertilizer  companies  to  farmers  follows  the  same  general 
pattern  as  that  for  mixed  fertilizers.  There  are,  however,  certain 
exceptions  on  carload  shipments  of  specified  materials  direct  from 
the  point  of  production  or  importer's  storage  warehouse.  Thus 
nitrate  of  soda  in  some  areas  is  quoted  ex  vessel  at  designated  ports  or, 
at  the  buyer's  option  for  a  small  premium,  f.  o.  b.  storage  warehouses 
at  the  same  ports.  Sulfate  of  ammonia  and  cyanamid  are  quoted  on 
the  same  basis  as  that  earlier  described  in  connection  with  commercial 
sales.  In  other  areas  special  terms  may  be  made  to  meet  competitive 
conditions.  Thus  nitrate  of  soda  in  one  area  is  currently  quoted 
delivered  to  the  farm  in  straight  carload  lots. 

As  might  be  expected  in  connection  with  any  structure  so  complex, 
it  is  subject  to  frequent  variation  to  meet  local  competitive  conditions. 
Either  the  list  price  or  the  terms  of  delivery  may  be  changed  as  a 
means  of  inducing  sales.  Thus  one  company  is  at  present  (Spring, 
1940)  allowing  special  freight  differentials  for  designated  delivery 
points  in  south  Alabama  and  in  Florida.  Regular  price  schedules 
are  often  supplemented  by  special  schedules  for  limited  periods  in 
order  to  meet  competition. 

247149 — 41 — No.  1 23 


328  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

PAPER    AND    PULP    INDUSTRIES 

Pulp  and  paper  are  bulky  items.  Freight  is  an  important  factor 
in  the  delivered  price.  Since  the  product  is  standardized,  it  is  not 
surprising  that  geographic  price  structures  have  become  somewhat 
conventionalized.  In  general  a  multiple  basing  point  system  is  char- 
acteristic of  pulp  markets  and  a  zone  system  of  the  markets  for  paper. 

Pulp. — The  market  pattern  for  pulp  reflects  the  pressure  of  imports 
from  Canada  and  Europe.  Prices  for  most  grades  of  pulp  are  quoted 
ex  dock,  ocean,  or  lake  ports.  Base  prices  are  usually  uniform  at 
Atlantic,  Gulf,  and  west  coast  ports.  Quotations  at  lake  ports  are 
usually  $2  per  ton  higher  than  these  base  prices  east  of  the  Straits  of 
Mackinac,  and  $3  per  ton  above  base  prices  west  of  the  Straits  of 
Mackinac.  These  differentials  are  approximately  equal  to  the  added 
cost  incurred  in  shipping  pulp  through  the  St.  Lawrence  River  to  the 
Lakes. 

At  inland  points  pulp  is  usually  sold  on  a  delivered  basis  with  the 
price  computed  by  adding  the  appropriate  amount  of  freight  to  the 
base  price  ex  dock  at  the  most  advantageously  located  port.  Most 
foreign  pulp  and  a  substantial  amount  of  domestic  pulp  actually 
passes  through  the  ports  which  serve  as  basing  points.  This  includes 
European  pulp,  some  pulp  originating  in  eastern  Canada,  and  domestic 
pulp  from  the  west  coast  which  is  shipped  by  water  to  the  East. 
Much  domestic  and  Canadian  pulp  does  not  actually  pass  through 
these  basing  points,  but  its  price  follows  that  which  applies  to  the 
bulk  of  the  water-borne  product. 

While  the  practices  described  are  generally  characteristic  of  the 
industry,  the  basing-point  system  is  not  strictly  adhered  to  by  all 
mills  on  all  sales.  All  foreign  pulp  (using  the  term  "foreign"  to 
exclude  both  domestic  and  Canadian)  follows  a  basing-point  structure, 
as  does  domestic  and  Canadian  bleached  sulfite.  However,  domestic 
and  Canadian  unbleached  sulfite,  bleached  and  unbleached  kraft 
and  ground  wood  pulp  are  imderstood  to  be  quoted  on  a  simple  de- 
Uvered-price  basis. 

Paper. — Most  paper  products  are  sold  at  delivored  prices  on  a 
zone  basis.  In  the  case  of  a  considerable  number  of  items,  however, 
the  zone  system  applies  to  the  resale  of  merchandise  by  distributors 
rather  than  to  its  initial  sale  by  paper  mills;  prices  on  the  latter 
transaction  vary  in  an  imsystematic  way.  The  number  of  zones  and 
their  relationship  varies  for  different  products. 

Newsprint. — There  are  10  zones  in  the  newsprint  market.  This 
number  is  materially  larger  than  that  for  any  other  paper  product, 
probably  because  the  cost  of  transportation  constitutes  a  major 
element  in  the  price  of  newsprint.  Dm-ing  1936  according  to  the 
Interstate  Commerce  Commission,*^  freight  revenue  amounted  to  22 
percent  of  the  delivered  value  of  newsprint  shipped  by  rail,  in  contrast 
with  ratios  of  from  4  to  6  percent  for  printing  paper,  wrapping  paper, 
and  paper  bags. 

I|n  the  operation  of  the  system,  the  fourth  zone,  which  includes  the 
western  border  of  the  Great  Lakes,  is  the  base  zone  and  prices  in  other 
areas  are  computed  by  means  of  more  or  less  fixed  differentials.  The 
lowest  prices  are  not  quoted  in  the  base  zones  but  in  zones  1  and  10, 

*•  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  op.  cit. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         329 

the  former  of  which  includes  metropolitan  New  York  and  the  latter 
the  Pacific  coast  and  the  southern  tip  of  Florida.  The  bulk  of  news- 
print consumption  occurs  within  territory  in  which  the  price  is  either 
the  base  price  or  less,*" 

Although  the  zone  system  is  generally  observed,  departures,  are 
apparently  not  infrequent.  These  may  occur  either  through  direct 
price  reductions  or  by  ignoring  zone  boundaries  on  particular  sales. 
It  is  understood  that  price  cutting  of  this  kind  is  most  frequent  in 
the  case  of  mills  selling  newsprint  in  their  immediate  vicinity.  Zone 
boundaries  themselves  are  also  subject  to  some  change  from  time  to 
time  in  adjustment  to  changing  competitive  conditions. 

Wrapping  paper,  tissue  paper,  and  paper  towels. — Price  quotations 
for  wrapping  paper,  tissue  paper,-  and  paper  towels  are  all  apparently 
on  a  zone  basis.  In  the  case  of  wrapping  paper  the  price  is  f.  o.  b. 
plant,  freight  allowed;  for  the  other  two  items  the  quotation  is  on  a 
delivered  basis.  Information  is  not  available  regarding  the  number  of 
zones  observed  in  the  case  of  wrapping  paper.  Current  quotations 
for  unbleached  roll  toilet  tissue  and  paper  towels,  both  bleached  and 
unbleached,  are  sold  on  the  basis  of  three  zones.  Zone  differentials 
vary  for  different  items  and  there  seems  to  be  no  regular  relationship 
between  the  prices  in  different  zones.  For  example,  cases  of  1,000- 
sheet  rolls  of  toilet  tissue  were  quoted  at  $3.50  in  zone  1,  $3.65  in 
zone  2,  and  $3.75  in  zone  3,  while  for  650-sheet  rolls  the  lowest  quota- 
tion was  for  zone  3  at  $2.85  a  case.  Zone  1  was  next  at  $3.10  a  case 
and  zone  2  at  $3.20  a  case.*^ 

Paper  board. — There  are  two  main  price  zones  observed  in  paper 
board  markets,  the  eastern  and  the  central.  The  eastern  territory 
extends  to  the  Alleghany  Mountains  and  the  central  territory  includes 
most  of  the  Middle  West.  In  addition  to  these  two  main. zones  there 
are  a  number  of  other  zones  of  minor  importance.  Thus  there  is  a 
small  zone  in  the  Southeast  in  which  prices  are  usaally  at  the  same 
level  as  in  the  eastern  zone.  There  is  also  a  small  zone  on  the  west 
coast  but  the  product  is  apparently  not  marketed  to  any  appreciable 
extent  in  that  area.  The  minor  importance  of  these  zones  is  suggested 
by  the  fact  that  oflficial  reporting  journals  "  do  not  quote  prices  for 
them.  For  most  types  of  paperboard,  prices  in  the  central  territory 
are  somewhat  higher  than  in  the  eastern,  but  the  differential  varies 
from  t  me  to  time  and  is  not  the  same  for  all  products.  In  some  cases 
at  least,  prices  in  the  eastern  territory  are  higher  than  in  the  central. 
Apparently  there  is  no  base  zone  which,  is  comparable  to  that  existing 
in  the  case  of  newsprint. 

Fine  paper. — Most  varieties  of  fine  paper  are  sold  on  the  basis 
of  distributors'  resale  zones.  Mill  prices  paid  by  distributors  ap- 
parently do  not  vary  in  any  clearly  defined  or  systematic  fashion. 
For  the  purposes  of  resale  by  distributors,  however,  the  United  States 
is  divided  into  four  zones,  and  prices  in  these  four  zones  for  the  many 
different  types  of  paper  products  sold  through  distributors  are  gener- 

'"  A  tabulation  prepared  bv  the  traffic  department  of  the  Chicago  Tribune,  for  use  in  connection  with  an 
Interstate  Commerce  Commission  case,  showed  that  in  1928,  80  to  85  percent  of  the  total  newsprint  con- 
sumption in  the  United  States  was  at  ports  or  In  zones  which  take  a  base  price  or  less.  The  secretary  of 
the  code  authority  of  the  newsprint  industry  speaking  in  193},  expressed  the  opinion  that  the  situation  had 
not  changed  very  much  as  of  that  time.  Hearings  on  Proposed  Recommendations  in  Respect  of  the  Stabil- 
ization of  the  Newsprint  Industry  and  the  Elimination  of  Unfair  Practices  and  Destructive  Competitive 
Prices,  February  1,  1934. 

>'  The  Paper  Mill  and  Wood  Pulp  News,  January  27,  1940,  p.  45. 

»'  Official  Board  Markets  and  Fiber  Containers. 


330  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

ally  uniform.  There  are  probably  a  number  of  factors  making  this 
type  of  price  structure  possible.  Paper  distributors  are  well  organized 
into  effective  trade  associations.  Moreover  a  substantial,  though 
undetermined,  amount  of  paper  is  distributed  by  manufacturers  on  a 
del  credere  basis  ^*  so  that  manufacturers  can  exercise  direct  control 
over  resale  prices.  In  some  ways  this  system  resembles  that  used  in 
the  case  of  refrigerators  where  distributors  buy  f.  o.  b.  mill  and  resell 
on  a  zone  basis. 

Paper  products. — Folding  paper  boxes,  which  are  one  of  the  most 
important  converted  paper  products,  are  sold  on  a  zone  basis.  It  is 
understood  that  there  are  12  zones.  This  zone  system  is  one  of  the 
practices  attacked  as  violating  the  antitrust  laws  in  an  indictment 
which  has  recently  been  issued  in  the  Federal  courts.  It  is  alleged 
that  it  constituted  one  element  in  a  "conspiracy  to  restrain  unreason- 
ably interstate  trade  in  corrugated  and  solid  fibre  board  shipping 
containers  by  unlawfully  supressing  and  restraining  competition 
among  association  members     *     *     *  "  64 

PASSENGER  AUTOMOBILES 

The  geographic  price  structure  for  the  distribution  of  motor  vehicles 
is  usually  thought  of  as  an  f.  o.  b.  plant  system,  yet  it  includes  man}* 
features  commonly  associated  with  the  use  of  basing  points.  The 
delivered  price  at  any  locality  is  arrived  at  by  adding  all-rail  freight 
from  the  manufacturer's  central  plant  or  headquarters  to  a  uniform 
f.  o.  b.  plant  price. 

The  significance  of  this  practice  should  be  interpreted  in  the  light 
of  the  known  characteristics  of  the  industry.  In  the  first  place,  there 
are  only  one  or  two  manufacturers  of  passenger  automobiles  whose 
main  plants  or  offices  are  located  outside  of  Michigan  and  these 
exceptions  are  not  among  the  largest  producers.  Consequently  prices 
"for  the  bulk  of  the  product  are  computed  on  the  basis  of  all-rail 
freight  from  Detroit  or  some  other  point  in  Michigan.  On  the  other 
hand,  a  large  and  probabl}^  increasing  proportion  of  cars  are  at  present 
being  assembled  at  points  outside  of  Michigan  and  many  of  the  parts 
entering  into  the  finished  vehicle  are  also  being  manufactured  at 
places  other  than  the  nominal  point  of  shipment.  Under  these 
circumstances  it  is  unlikely  that  the  actual  cost  of  shipping  parts  to 
the  assembly  plant  and  then  transporting  the  finished  vehicle  to  the 
point  of  delivery  will  be  the  same  as  the  all-rail  freight  from  the  central 
plant  to  destination.  Moreover  a  substantial  and  probably  increasing 
proportion  of  the  total  number  of  automobiles  produced  is  shipped  to 
destination  either  entirely  or  part  way  by  truck  or  water;  yet,  the 
delivered  price  is  always  computed  on  the  basis  of  all-rail  freight. 

Consequently  the  price  structure,  at  least  for  passenger  automobiles, 
has  many  of  the  characteristics  of  the  single  basing  point  system,  with 
the  exception  that  instead  of  all  companies  charging  freight  from  some 
single  agreed  point,  such  as  Detroit,  each  company  quotes  from  the 
location  of  its  own  home  plant  or  office.  In  view  of  the  high  concentra- 
tion of  all  producers  in  Michigan,  however,  this  variation  is  not  of 

w  The  distributor  acts  as  the  manufacturer's  agent  in  making  the  sale,  but  assumes  the  added  function  of 
guaranteeing  the  credit  of  the  buyer. 

«  U.  S.  V.  National  Container  Association  et  al.  (District  Court  for  the  Southern  District  of  New  York, 
Aiieust  1939  terra,  returned  August  9,  1939). 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  331 

major  significance;  for  all  practical  purposes  prices  paid  by  buyers 
vary  in  much  the  same  way  as  they  would  if  an  orthodox  basing  point 
scheme  were  used. 

AGRICULTURAL  IMPLEMENTS  AND  MACHINERY 

The  general  basis  of  quotation  in  this  industry  is  f .  o.  b.  plant.  A 
few  large  producers,  however,  maintain  factories  in  a  number  of 
difTorent  places.  One  of  these  is  usually  the  headquarters  plant, 
producing  a  wide  line  of  equipment,  while  the  others  may  be  more 
specialized.  As  a  result  the  customary  practice  is  to  charge  freight 
either  from  the  main  plant  or  from  the  actual  plant  of  shipment, 
whichever  results  in  a  lower  price  to  the  dealer.  This  seems  to  be 
equivalent  to  a  system  of  intra-company  freight  equalization. 

The  system  described  is  generally  adhered  to  on  all  transactions  west 
of  the  Rocky  Mountains,  and  also  east  of  the  Rocky  Mountains  on 
sales  of  tractors,  harvester-threshers,  binders,  mowers,  cream  sepa- 
rators, milkers,  and  belt-power  machines.  In  the  case  of  plows, 
harrows,  cultivators,  and  other  ground-working  implements,  however, 
some  manufacturers,  including  at  least  one  very  large  producer, 
adhere  to  the  f.  o.  b.  factory  or  headquarters  basis,  while  others  sell 
f.  o.  b.  established  Missouri  River  points  (or  MinneapoUs)  for 
central  western  territories  and  f.  o.  b.  branch  houses  in  eastern  terri- 
tories. This  latter  practice  probably  reflects  the  historical  develop- 
ment of  the  industry.  Originally  implements  were  usually  distributed 
through  local  wholesale  jobbers,  who,  in  pricing  goods,  added  their 
freight  cost  to  the  price  which  they  paid  to  manufacturers.  For 
practical  purposes  this  was  usually  equivalent  to  f.  o.  b.  Missouri 
River  points  and  Minneapolis,  which  were  the  centers  of  wholesale 
distribution  for  the  Middle  West.  As  distribution  gradually  shifted 
from  jobbers  to  company-owned  branch  houses,  the  practice  of  quoting 
f.  o".  b.  Missouri  River  points  and  Minneapolis  was  retained  by  some 
concerns  for  the  types  of  product  for  which  this  had  been  the  tradi- 
tional practice.  Implements  which  were  introduced  after  the  change 
in  distributive  practice,  including  much  of  the  newer,  heavier,  me- 
chanical equipment,  are  quoted  by  all  concerns  on  the  f.  o.  b.  plant 
basis. 

In  order  to  reduce  freight  charges  to  a  minimum,  dealers  may  avail 
themselves  of  the  storage-in-transit  privilege  (giving  the  dealer  most  of 
the  advantage  of  through  rates)  on  goods  shipped  to  dealers  through 
branches.  In  this  way  the  delivered  price  to  the  dealer  will  be  based 
upon  the  through  rate  from  the  plant  and  not  upon  the  sum  of  the 
straight  haul  rates  from  factory  to  distributor  and  from  distributor  to 
dealer.  Pool  car  shipments  can  also  be  used  to  permit  several  dealers 
to  combine  their  requirements  into  full  carloads  and  thus  to  avoid  the 
extra  cost  of  1.  c.  1.  freight.  The  general  practices  which  have  been 
described  are  apparently  modified  to  some  extent  by  unsystematic 
freight  absorption  to  meet  competition  in  individual  cases. 

MACHINERY  AND  RELATED  PRODUCTS 

(Other  than  automotive  and  agricultural) 

In  general  the  market  for  machinery  (other  than  automotive  and 
agricmtural)  may  be  considered  to  embrace  two  distinct  types  of 


332  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

transaction;  those  in  which  the  product  is  made  to  order  to  the 
specifications  of  the  buyer  and  those  in  which  the  product  is  a  standard 
item  regularly  stocked  and  distributed  by  the  seller. 

In  transactions  of  the  first  sort,  relating  to  made-to-order  equip- 
ment, each  sale  constitutes  essentially  a  separate  contract,  all  terms 
of  which  are  subject  to  direct  bargaining.  The  cost  of  shipment 
merely  comprises  one  of  the  terras  which  must  be  considered  by  the 
seller  in  determining  his  offer  and  which  the  buyer  will  take  into  ac- 
count in  deciding  whose  offer  to  accept.  It  is  understood  that  the 
bulk  of  these  contract  sales  are  on  an  f.  o.  b.  plant  basis,  in  which  case 
the  price  quoted  by  the  seller  undoubtedly  reflects  the  availability 
of  competing  offers  from  more  advantageously  located  plants.  If  the 
terms  of  the  contract  contemplate  installation,  then  the  element  of 
freight  is,  of  course,  included  directly  in  the  quotation  or  bid.  In 
either  event,  since  each  transaction  of  this  kind  is  in  a  sense  unique, 
it  cannot  be  strictly  said  that  any  geographic  price  structure  exists 
in  the  ordinary  sense.  While  no  accurate  figures  are  available,  it 
has  been  estimated  that  the  majority  of  industrial  machinery  in  terms 
of  dollar  volume  is  sold  on  a  contract  basis. 

'  The  second  major  type  of  transaction  involves  standard  items 
which  are  produced  in  suJQBcient  quantity  to  warrant  the  seller  in 
quoting  a  regular  list  price.  Items  of  this  kind  are  frequently  called 
"catalogue  items"  to  indicate  that  they  are  described  and  quoted  in 
a  catalogue  or  other  list  issued  by  the  producer.  This  group  includes 
most  of  the  smaller  varieties  of  machinery  such  as  electric  motors  of 
moderate  size,  standard  pumps,  and  similar  types  of  equipment  which 
are  not  made  to  order  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  individual  buyer. 
Apparently  most  products  of  this  kind  are  sold  on  a  delivered  basis, 
using  the  postage  stamp  or  the  zone  system,  though  at  least  one  large 
manufacturer  adheres  to  straight  f.  o.  b.  plant  pricing.  The  practice 
followed  varies  for  different  branches  of  the  industry  and  is  not  always 
standardized  even  as  between  competing  companies  manufacturing 
similar  products.  The  following  information  is  the  best  available 
regarding  the  practices  encountered  in  the  sales  of  different  kinds  of 
machinery. 

Electrical  machinery  and  apparatus. — A  comprehensive  study  of 
pricing  practices  in  the  electrical  machinery  and  apparatus  industry 
was  conducted  by  the  Division  of  Review  of  the  National  Recovery 
Administration  during  the  latter  part  of  1935.  This  survey  related 
largely  to  standard,  small  items  and  little  data  were  compiled  regard- 
ing heavier  industrial  machinery.     According  to  this  report — 

Inasmuch  as  most  manufacturers  of  electrical  products  sell  their  products  over 
a  wide  geographical  area,  the  problem  of  transportation  enters  into  the  price 
contract.  The  manufacturer  frequently  includes  freight  as  part  of  the  total 
sale.  The  extreme  forms  which  the  price  structure  may  take  is  sale  f .  o.  b.  factory 
or  a  delivered  price  regardless  of  the  customer's  location.-  Other  variations  are 
the  use  of  basing  points,  i.  e.,  freight  charged  from  some  point  other  than  the 
factory,  and  the  use  of  zones,  the  most  usual  being  some  variant  on  the  theme  of 
east  and  west.  Perhaps  the  most  unusual  is  the  pole  line  hardware  group,  having 
three  ^ones,  one  of  which  is  the  single  State,  Arizona.  In  several  groups,  the 
treatment  of  freight  varies  among  the  classes  of  customers,  while  in  many  the 
character  of  the  freight  charge  or  allowance  varies  with  the  size  of  the  order,  a 
iorm  of  quantity  discount. 

It  has  usually  been  assumed  that  the  freight  element  in  the  price  structure 
changes  but  little  from  time  to  time.  It  is  possible,  of  course,  that  such  changes 
were  largely  the  result  of  the  new  information  suddenly  made  available  about 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         333 

the  practices  of  others  in  the  industry,  and  that  it  was  inevitable  that  there  would 
be  numerous  changes  in  the  first  year  of  price-filing.  This  would  argue  that  the 
record  of  change  was  merely  temporary.  Certainly,  the  filings  for  the  groups 
studied  show  that  freight  terms  are  by  no  means  inflexible.  However,  changes 
were  not  merely  along  the  line  of  the  development  of  uniformity.  The  outstand- 
ing (sic)  is  that  of  the  rubber-covered  building  wire  group,  whose  price  structure 
changed  from  an  elaborate  system  of  freight  charges  to  a  delivered  price  basis 
during  the  period.  This  is  not  an  isolated  case  of  structural  change,  for  other 
groups  also  recorded  revised  freight  structures. 

One  form  of  price  change  under  this  head  relates  to  the  companies  which  charge 
freiglit  from  various  warehousing  points.  Since  they  abandon  or  add  warehouses 
from  time  to  time  the  result  is  an  unrecorded  change  in  prices.'* 

Specific  information  is  available  in  this  report  with  regard  to  geo- 
graphic pricing  practices  used  for  the  following  branches  of  the  in- 
dustry during  National  Recovery  Administration, 

(1)  Wire,  including  rubber  covered  building  wire,  magnet  wire,  and 
flexible    cords. ^® 

For  all  these  products,  the  general  practice  at  the  end  of  the  code 
period  was  to  quote  a  uniform  delivered  price  on  all  shipments  of 
100  pounds  or  more  but  to  sell  shipments  of  less  than  100  pounds  on  an 
f.  o.  b.  plant  basis,  purchaser  paying  full  freight.  There  were  some 
variations  in  this  practice,  as,  for  example,  in  the  case  of  certain  manu- 
facturers of  flexible  cords  who  relaxed  the  1 00-pound  minimum  require- 
ment for  freight  absorption  in  the  case  of  individual  sales  to  a  few 
large  distributors. 

(2)  Electric  fans." 

The  general  practice  was  to  quote  prices  f .  o.  b.  destination  on  orders 
of  100  pounds  or  more  when  the  point  of  destination  was  a  city  in  which 
a  distributor's  warehouse  was  located.  Smaller  orders  were  f.  o.  b. 
point  of  shipment.  Apparently  the  practical  effect  of  this  type  of 
structure  for  orders  exceeding  100  pounds  would  be  to  make  each  city 
in  which  a  distributor's  warehouse  was  located  a  basing  point,  with 
prices  uniform  at  each  basing  point.  Toward  the  latter  part  of  the 
code  period,  it  became  the  practice  to  quote  all  Government  inquiries 
f.  o.  b.  destination  regardless  of  weight. 

(3)  Fractional  horsepower  electric  motors  and  electric  arc  welding 
apparatus.^* 

Price  quotations  were  f.o.  b.  factory,  fuU  freight  allowed  to  destina- 
tion. 

(4)  Dry  cells  and  flashlights.^^ 

There  was  a  wide  variation  in  the  practices  used  in  this  branch  of 
the  industry.  Sales  to  toy  manufacturers  were  apparently  sold  f.  o,  b. 
factory  in  all  cases;  mail-order  houses  and  chain  stores  were  quoted 
f.  o.  b.  destination  in  carload  lots  and  f.  o.  b.  warehouses  on  1.  c.  1. 
,  sales.  In  the  case  of  one  product — the  number  6  dry  cell — there 
seems  to  have  been  a  zone  system  with  a  higher  delivered  price  west 
of  the  Rocky  Mountains  than  in  the  East.  For  the  radio  B-battery, 
however,  prices  were  uniform  throughout  the  country. 

(5)  Radio  receiving  tubes. ^'^ 

w  A  Study  of  Open  Price  Filing  in  the  Electrical  Manufacturing  Industry  by  W.  L.  Thorp  and  A.  H. 
Caesar,  with  the  assistance  of  F.  W.  Powell,  Work  Materials  No.  78,  National  Recovery  Administration, 
vol.  I,  p.  177. 

M  Ibid,  pp.  10-53. 

"  Ibid.,  pp.  71-79. 

«« Ibid.,  pp.  56-64,  82-88. 

M  Ibid.,  pp.  96-108. 

^Ibid.,  pp.  111-117. 


334  CONCENTRATION  OF  EXX)NOMIC  POWER 

The  freight  structure  for  this  product  seems  to  have  been  so  con- 
fused that  it  was  impossible  to  derive  any  generalization.  According 
to  this  report,  "Freight  is  usually  f.  o.  b.  destination  or  f.  o.  b.  plant. 
There  are  in  addition  numerous  exceptions  such  as  'freight  allowed  to 
destination  on  shipments  to  set  manufacturers',  'prepaid  50  tubes  or 
more',  'prepaid  any  quantity  New  York  area',  'prepaid  on  100  or 
more',  and  others  based  on  order  or  customer  class  involved." 

(6)  Sockets." 

On  orders  of  100  pounds,  f.  o.  b.  freight  was  allowed  to  any  point  in 
the  United  States;  smaller  orders  were  f.  o.  b.  plant;  special  treatment 
on  some  sales  was  allowed  to  syndicate  stores  by  certain  companies. 

(7)  Domestic  electric  heating  appliances. ^^ 

The  general  practice  was  to  quote  prices  f.  o.  b.  factory.  There 
were,  however,  some  companies  which  quoted  delivered  prices  on 
orders  of  100  pounds  or  more,  orders  sent  to  Metropolitan  New  York, 
or  orders  f.  o.  b.  warehouse. 

(8)  Food  service  equipment.*^ 

This  branch  of  the  industry  included  "electrically  operated  or  heated 
counter  appliances,  bake  ovens,  dish  washers,  meat  choppers,  coffee 
mills,  potato  peelers,  drink  mixers,  slicers,  silver  burnishers,  and  other 
similar  appliances."  According  to  the  report  this  diversity  in  product 
was  reflected  in  a  similar  diversity  in  type  of  structure: 

Durir^  the  period  of  open  price  filing,  at  least  28  varying  sets  of  delivery  terms 
were  us^d.  *  *  *  These  terms  varied  from  a  simple  statement,  such  as  f.  o.  b. 
factory,  to  delivered  prices  on  a  zone  basis.  No  trend  toward  simplification  or 
uniformity  is  evident. 

(9)  Laminated  phenolic  products.** 

These  products  are  plastics,  usually  referred  to  as  bakelite,  and  are 
widely  used  for  the  purpose  of  insulation.  They  were  sold  on  the 
basis  of  a  zone  system.  Freight  was  allowed  on  shipments  east  of 
the  eastern  boundary  of  Montana,  Utah,  Wyoming,  and  Arizona. 
On  shipments  west  of  this  line,  5  percent  was  added  to  the  net  price 
and  freight  was  prepaid. 

(10)  Nonremovable  plug  fuses.** 

Freight  was  allowed  to  destination  on  sales  to  very  large  buyers, 
wholesalers,  syndicates,  chains,  and  the  United  States  Government; 
quotations  to  other  buyers  were  f.  o.  b.  factory  or  warehouse. 

(11)  Fanelboards.«« 

This  branch  of  the  industry  used  a  two-zone  system,  with  the  line 
of  demarcation  at  102  degrees  west  longitude.  There  were  numerous 
variations  for  specific  points. 

(12)  Pole  line  hardware.*^ 

There  were  three  distinct  zones;  the  western  division  and  eastern 
division,  and  one  division  comprising  only  the  State  of  Arizona.  Not 
only  prices  but  other  terms  of  sale  varied  in  each  of  the  three  geo- 
graphic areas.  The  reason  for  the  special  treatment  of  Arizona,  in 
which  prices  were  higher  than  in  either  of  the  two  other  divisions,  is 
not  clear. 


I 


«  Ibid.,  pp.  120-128. 
« Ibid.,  pp.  133-140. 
M  Ibid,  pp.  142-148. 
**  Ibid,  pp.  153-162. 
••  Ibid,  pp.  168-169. 
••  Ibid,  pp.  170-171. 
« Ibid,  pp.  171-173. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER  335 

Since  this  study  of  practices  under  the  National  Recovery  Adminis- 
tration Codes  was  made  in  1935,  numerous  changes  have  undoubtedly 
occurred,  but  it  has  been  impractical,  within  the  time  limits  for  this 
study,  to  make  a  detailed  inquiry.  Evidence  of  some  change  is  in- 
dicated by  the  fact  that  cease-and-desist  orders,  issued  by  the  Federal 
Trade  Conunission,  have  been  directly  concerned  with  geographic 
pricing  practices  in  the  electrical  machuiery  industry.  The  first  of 
these,  which  was  issued  on  December  29,  1936,  directed  the  National 
Electric  Manufacturers'  Association  and  others  to  cease  and  desist 
from  maintaining  uniform  delivered  prices  either  throughout  the 
United  States  or  by  zones  for  power  cable  and  "safecote"  rubber- 
covered  building  wire.^  The  second,  which  was  issued  on  April  2, 
1937,  ordered  the  General  Electric  Co.  and  the  Westinghouse  Electric 
&  Manufacturing  Co.,  and  other  respondents,  to  stop  selling  turbine 
generators  and  condensers  at  uniform  delivered  prices.®® 

More  current  information  regarding  geographic  pricing  practices  in 
this  branch  of  the  industry  is  generally  limited.  However,  according 
to  Mund,^°  the  system  of  granting  full  freight  allowance  for  electrical 
equipment  is  still  conunon.  Thus,  rubber-covered  building  wire, 
electric  lamps,  cable  accessories  and  magnet  wire,  turbines,  lightning 
arrestors,  and  switch  gear  are  all  quoted  f.  o.  b.  plant  with  freight  al- 
lowed and  prepaid  to  destination.  Arc  welding  electrodes,  power 
cable-,  street-lighting  equipment  and  distribution  transformers  are 
sold  with  freight  allowance  within  specified  zones.  Portable  electric 
tools,  dry-cell  batteries  and  flashlights,  electric  fans,  and  many  other 
varieties  of  electric  merchandise  are  quoted  freight  allowed  to  dis- 
tributors. In  most  of  these  cases,  some  minimum  shipment  (usually 
100  pounds)  must  be  ordered  in  order  to  receive  the  allowance.^^ 

Milling ,  machines,  grinding  machines,  screw  machines,  etc. — There 
is  some  conflict  in  evidence  as  to  the  geographic  structure  most  com- 
monly observed  in  the  sale  of  catalogue  items  falling  into  this  category. 
One  leading  producer  quotes. on  a  straight  f.  o.  b.  plant  basis,  with  no 
provision  for  equalization  and  explains  this  policy  on  the  ground  that 
diflFerences  in  design,  often  protected  by  patented  features,  make  pos 
sible  a  substantial  degree  of  nonprice  emphasis.  There  are,  however, 
some  reports  of  the  use  of  freight  equalization  by  other  sellers. 

Engines,  turbines,  water  wheels,  and  windmills. — The  heavier  items  in 
this  group  are  contract  items  which  do  not  fall  into  any  clear  category 
as  regards  geographical  pricing  practice.  It  is  understood  that  lighter 
standard  products,  such  as  light  diesel  and  gasoline  engines,  are  sold 
at  dehvered  prices  which  tend  to  be  uniform  throughout  the  United 
States. 

Pumps. — Pumps  are  usually  sold  on  a  uniform  delivered  price  basis 
throughout  the  country,  but  practice  is  not  uniform.  In  some  cases 
the  same  practice  is  followed  on  sales  of  combinations  of  pumps  and 
pumping  engines,  probably  because  both  these  products  are  frequently 
manufactured  by  the  same  companies.  On  the  other  hand,  one 
manufacturer  of  windmiU  type  pumps,  which  can  be  operated  either 
by  a  windmill  or  an  engine,  is  reported  to  be  selling  on  an  f.  o.  b. 
factory  basis. 

••  F.  T.  C.  Docket  No.  2565. 

••  F.  T.  C.  Docket  No.  2941. 

'"Op.-oit. 

"  Ibid,  pp.  232,  237. 


336  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

ExcavatiTig  and  road  machinery. — In  discussing  industrial  plant 
machinery  it  was  pointed  out  that  cheaper  items  were  usually  standard 
in  design  ^while  more  expensive  products  were  made  to  order  on  the 
basis  of  individual  contracts.  In  the  case  of  excavating  and  road 
machinery,  such  as  steam  shovels,  although  the  individual  product  is 
usually  quite  expensive,  it  is  nevertheless  more  or  less  standardized. 
Consequently,  there  is  a  tendency  for  prices  to  be  adjusted  to  the 
needs  of  the'  individual  transaction,  even  though  the  item  may  be  of 
standard  design.  According  to  the  best  information  available,  sales 
are  usually  on  an  f.  o.  b.  factory  basis,  but  the  seller  is  likely  to  adjust 
his  offer  on  any  unsystematic  basis  in  order  to  compete  with  other 
sellers  located  nearer  the  point  of  destination. 

Business  and  trade  equipment. — Although  the  Census  of  Manu- 
factures includes  such  items  as  business  machines,  scales,  and  balances 
in  the  general  category  of  machinery,  they  are,  of  course,  essentially 
different  in  market  characteristics.  Since  freight  is  a  smaller  relative 
element  in  the  cost  of  these  products  than  for  machinery  generally, 
there  is  apparently  a  greater  tendency  for  the  maintenance  of  uniform 
delivered  prices.  Typewriters  are  generally  sold  on  a  uniform  delivered 
price  basis  anywhere  in  the  United  States.  The  same  is  probably  true  of 
conmiercial  scales  and  balances,  comptometers  and  calculating 
machines,  accounting  machines,  and  similar  office  equipment.  How- 
ever, at  least  one  manufacturer  of  industrial  scales  sells  on  a  zone  basis 
through  the  use  of  varying  discounts  from  list  prices  for  different 
parts  of  the  country. 

ELECTRICAL    HOUSEHOLD    EQUIPMENT 

Electric  refrigerators. — The  geographic  price  structure  of  the 
electrical  refrigerator  industry  presents  a  combination  of  an  f.  o.  b. 
factory  system  at  the  wholesale  level  and  a  zone  price  system  at  the 
retail  level. 

The  most  common'  channel  of  distribution  for  this  product  is  from 
manufacturer  to  wholesale  distributor  to  dealer  to  consumer.  Sales 
by  manufacturers  to  wholesale  distributors  are  on  a  simple  f.  o.  b. 
plant  basis;  there  is  no  evidence  of  the  use  of  any  scheme  of  freight 
absorption  or  equalization.^^  Consequently,  the  delivered  prices  paid 
by  distributors  vary  with  their  distance  freightwise  from  the  plant. 
According  to  the  price  list  of  one  manufacturer,  the  approximate 
average  carload  freight  from  his  plant  in  the  Middle  West  to  points  on 
the  west  coast  is  $1.55  per  hundred  poimds.  This  is  equivalent  to 
between  $6  and  $7  for  a  typical  6-cubic-foot  refrigerator  weighing 
about  400  pounds  and  quoted  at  slightly  over  $100^  f.  o.  b.  factory. 

This  point-to-point  variation  in  delivered  prices  paid  by  distributors 
is  not  reflected  in  a  similar  pattern  in  retail  markets.  This  is  probably 
due  in  part  to  the  merchandising  policy  of  most  manufacturers  which 
contemplates  some  degree  of  control  over  the  retail  price  level.  In 
addition,  retail  prices  are  affected  to  some  extent  by  the  practice  of 
price  lining  which  is  described  in  detail  in  another  chapter  of  this 
report.^* 

Since  freight  constitutes  a  substantial  element  on  shipments  to 
areas  remote  from  the  plant,  national  uniformity  of  retail  prices  would 

"  These  comments  refer  to  current  practice.    However,  In  1937  at  least  one  company  allowed  carlot  freight 
to  the  distributor's  city. 
)i  Appendix  II,  p.  249. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


337 


be  difficult  to  maintain,  and  a  zone  system  has  been  adopted  as  a 
compromise.  The  general  practice  divides  the  country  into  four 
zones,  though  at  least  one  manufacturer  uses  only  three  and,  since  1940, 
one  concern  has  combined  the  entire  region  east  of  the  Rockies  into  a 
single  zone.  Price  variations  between  zones  correspond  roughly  to 
the  average  cost  of  shipment  into  the  zones.  The  zone  system  applies 
to  sales  by  distributors  to  retail  dealers  as  well  as  on  retail  sales  to 
consumers.  The  variation  between  the  point-to-point  system  followed 
on  sales  by  manufacturers  and  the  zone  price  structure  is  therefore 
absorbed  by  the  distributors ;  those  located  in  the  portion  of  the  zone 
nearest  the  plant  are  able  to  obtain  a  slightly  higher  mark-up  than 
those  on  the  outer  boundaries  of  the  zone.  However,  this  variation 
may  not  be  very  important  and  it  probably  does  not  exceed  $1  or  $2 
a  unit. 

Unlike  industries  in  which  zone  boundaries  have  been  rigidly  fixed 
by  custom  and  are  universally  observed,  each  manufacturer  apparently 
adjusts  his  zoning  system  to  meet  his  own  particular  requirements. 
Thus,  one  manufacturer  whose  plant  is  in  Detroit  includes  all  of  New 
England  in  his  first  or  lowest-priced  zone;  a  competitor  whose  plant 
is  in  Chicago  includes  only  the  area  immediately  adjacent  to  Chicago 
as  his  home  zone,  and  classes  not  only  New  England,  but  also  the  entire 
eastern  seaboard  nopth  of  South  Carolina  as  his  third  zone.  Pre- 
sumably these  variations  are  made  possible  by  the  fact  that  refrigera- 
tors are  differentiated  products  so  that  minor  price  differences  between 
similar  models  can  readily  exist  in  the  same  market. 

The  actual  extent  of  price  variation  for  a  typical  6-foot  refrigerator 
at  each  marketing  level  is  indicated  in  the  following  table.  Price 
differences  at  the  retail  level  expressed  in  absolute  figures  are  some- 
what greater  than  at  the  distributive  levels  but,  when  expressed  in 
terms  of  percentage,  mark-ups  are  about  the  same  in  all  areas.  The 
influence  of  "price  lines"  upon  the  retail  price  structure  is  evident. 

Table  3. — Prices  of  electric  refrigerators 


Zone 

F.  0.  b.  to 
distributor 

Average 

freight  to 

zone> 

Totnl  de- 
livered cost 

to  dis- 
tributor • 

Cost  to  re- 
tailM « 

Retail  price 
to  con- 
sumer ' 

1 

$04.31 
94.31 
94.31 
94.31 

!i!2.63 
4.31 
5.25 
6.81 

$96.94 
98.62 
99.56 

100.12 

$111.22 
112.47 
114. 34 
115. 59 

$182. 95 

2 

184  95 

8 

187. 95 

4 

189. 95 

'  Varies  from  point  to  point  within  zone. 
•  Uniform  throughout  zone. 

Sonrce:  Manufacturer's  printed  price  list. 

Since  the  beginning  of  1940,  there  have  been  substantial  price  read- 
justments in  the  industry,  but  geographic  price  relationships  appear  to 
have  been  generally  retained  upon  the  same  basis.  However,  as  men- 
tioned above,  one  large  producer  now  observes  only  two  zones,  east 
and  west  of  the  Rockies. 

Electric  washing  machines  and  ranges. — The  geographic  price  struc- 
ture observed  by  most  manufacturers  of  electric  washing  machines  and 
ranges  is  similar  in  all  important  respects  to  that  described  for  electric 
refrigerators. 


338  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Vacuum  cleaners  and  fans. — The  practices  prevailing  during  Na- 
tional Recovery  Administration  in  connection  with  the  sale  of  electric 
fans  have  been  discussed  in  connection  with  the  general  consideration 
of  electrical  machinery  and  apparatus.  The  same  system  is  observed 
currently  and  applies  also  to  the  sale  of  vacuum  cleaners  On  ship- 
ments of  100  pounds  or  more,  freight  is  prepaid,  resulting  in  a  uniform 
nation-wide  delivered  price.  When  the  shipment  is  less  than  100 
pounds,  the  buyer  pays  the  freight. 

NONFERROUS    METALS 

There  are  wide  variations  in  the  geographic  price  structures  ob- 
served in  the  sale  of  different  nonferrous  metals.  In  some  cases 
totally  different  structures .  may  even  apply  to  different  grades  of 
the  same  metal.  Since  it  is  impractical  to  describe  these  price  sys- 
tems for  anything  approaching  a  complete  list,  a  few  of  the  more 
important  metals  have  been  selected  to  illustrate  the  types  of  vari- 
ation which  are  encountered. 

Aluminum. — Aluminum  is  sold  at  a  uniform  delivered  price  any- 
where in  the  United  States.  Since  this  product  is  subject  to  a  virtu- 
ally complete  monopoly,  the  choice  of  price  system  presumably  repre- 
sents a  decision  as  to  marketing  expediency  bythe  Aluminum  Co.  of 
America.  The  reasons  for  this  choice  of  policy  are  not  obvious,  though 
it  is  possible  that  its  simpUcity  may  be  an  important  consideration. 
The  relatively  minor  importance  of  freight  as  a  cost  element  is  pre- 
sumably a  factor;  according  to  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission 
freight  revenue  on  shiptnents  of  aluminum  amounted  to  only  3.24 
percent  of  value  at  destination  for  the  calendar  year  1936. 

Zinc. — There  are  three  primary  grades  of  zinc;  in  order  of  increas- 
ing purity,  these  are  Prime  Western.  Brass  Special,  and  High  Grade 
Electrolytic.  Approximately  30  percent  of  production,  by  volume, 
falls  into  each  of  the  first  two  grades  and  the  remaining  40  percent  is 
Electrolytic.  The  most  important  use  of  prime  western  zinc  is  for 
galvanizing.  The  Brass  grade,  as  implied  in  the  name,  is  used  for 
brass  production.  High  Grade  Electrolytic,  which  is  approximately 
99.9  percent  pure,  is  used  in  the  electrical  and  chemical  industries. 

The  Prime  Western  and  the  Brass  grades  are  both  sold  on  the  basis 
of  a  single  basing  point  at  East  St.  Louis,  III.  Although  a  New  York 
price  for  these  products  is  regularly  quoted  in  trade  publications,  this 
is  arrived  at  simply  by  adding  freight  to  the  East  St.  Louis  quotation 
and  does  not  imply  the  existence  of  an  additional  basing  point  in  New 
York.  In  interpreting  this  practice,  it  is  of  interest  that  there  is  no 
large  concentration  of  production  at  East  St.  Louis,  so  that  the  situ- 
ation differs  from  that  in  the  Mec\  industry  where  Pittsburgh  is  a 
major  producing  area.  There  is  in  fact  only  one  active  smelter  at 
St.  Louis.  However,  the  tri-State  area  of  Missouri,  Oklahoma,  and 
Kansas,  which  is  located  within  three  or  four  hundred  miles  of  East 
St.  Louis,  is  the  largest  producing  area  in  the  country.  It  is  under- 
stood that  transportation  costs  from  the  principal  producing  points  to 
major  consuming  centers  average  out  roughly  when  computed  fronv 
East  St.  Louis.  The  character  of  the  railroad  freight  structure  is  a 
contributing  factor.  The  freight  rate  from  middle  western  zinc 
smelters  (west  of  the  Mississippi  River),  which  account  for  the  bulk 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  339 

of  production  to  the  chief  consuming  centers,  is  said  to  be  approxi- 
mately equal  to  the  sum  of  the  rates  from  smelters  to  East  St.  Louis 
and  from  East  St.  Louis  to  destination,  although  some  deviation  may 
occur.  On  the  other  hand,  there  is  one  important  producer  in  New 
Jersey  which,  although  remote  from  the  basing  point,  observes  the 
same  geographic  structure. 

The -actual  form  of  quotation  may  be  either  f.  o.  b.  East  St.  Louis,  or 
delivered  including  freight  from  East  St.  Louis.  Quotations  on  the 
latter  basis  are  sometimes  slightly  higher  than  on  the  former  because 
a  delay  is  involved  in  settlement  for  the  purchase  so  that  interest 
charges  may  be  added. 

As  is  true  m  other  industries,  large  buyers  are  often  able  to  obtam 
concessions  from  nominal  quotations,  though  prices  to  smaller  users 
follow  the  basing  point  structure  quite  closely.  In  general  the  sys- 
tem seems  to  be  more  closely  adhered  to  for  the  Prime  Western  grade 
than  for  the  Brass  grades,  because  the  latter  are  produced  largely  to 
order. 

Electrolytic  zinc,  in  contrast  to  the  other  two  grades,  is  sold  at 
imiform  delivered  prices  anywhere  in  the  United  States.  The 
reasons  for  this  difference  in  practice  have  not  been  determined. 

Lead. — The  price  structure  for  lead  is  not  as  well  defined  as  that 
for  zinc.  As  in  the  case  of  zinc,  the  general  structure  is  a  basing- 
point  system  with  St.  Louis,  Mo.,  as  the  base.  However,  prices  are 
also  quoted  at  New  York  and  the  relationship  between  St.  Louis  and 
New  York  prices  varies.  New  York  prices  are  higher  than  those  at 
St.  Louis  but  not  necessarily  by  the  amount  equivalent  to  the  freight 
difference.  As  a  result  both  of  these  cities  are  basing  points,  with 
delivered  prices  determined  by  a  lower  sum  of  base  price  and  freight 
from  destination.  Part  of  the  variation  between  price  trends  at 
New  York  and  St.  Louis  is  attributed  to  the  competition  of  imports 
at  New-  York. 

The  price  structure  for  lead  tends  to  be  somewhat  flexible  because 
of  the  fact  that  one  large  producer — the  American  Smelting  &  Re- 
fining Co. — often  quotes  prices  somewhat  lower  than  those  announced 
by  the  acknowledged  price  leader  in  the  industry — the  St.  Joseph 
Lead  Co.  Under  such  circumstances,  adherence  to  the  nominal 
geographic  structure  is  probably  not  always  close. 

Copper. — Copper  is  almost  always  sold  at  delivered  prices.  For 
electrolytic  copper,  which  represents  roughly  85  percent  of  the  copper 
consumption  of  the  United  States,  this  practice  means  chiefly  de- 
livered at  the  Connecticut  Valley,  where  most  of  the  brass  mills,  con- 
stituting the  biggest  consumers  of  this  form  of  copper,  are  located. 
However  some  copper,  mainly  that  sold  for  electrical  purposes,  is 
delivered  at  other  points,  principally  in  New  York  and  New  England. 

On  the  bulk  of  all  electrolytic  copper  that  is  sold,  the  delivered 
prices  are  arrived  at  on  the  basis  of  an  f.  o.  b.  New  York  price  plus 
charges  for  transportation  and  interest  from  New  York.  This  situa- 
tion arises  from  the  fact  that  approximately  90  percent  of  all  copper 
refining  is  done  in  the  vicinity  of  New  York  City."^  There  are  said 
to  be  only  three  refineries  located  outside  this  area — one  at  Great 
Falls,  Mont.,  from  which  the  copper  is  shipped  mainly  to  the  Con- 

'*  The  smelters  for  the  copper  ore  are  all  located  in  the  West.  The  product  of  the  smelters,  blister  copper^ 
is  shipped  to  the  refineries  and  generally  is  refined  under  a  toll  arrangement.  Very  little  blister  copper, 
as  such,  is  sold. 


340  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

necticut  Valley,  one  at  Baltimore  where  the  copper  is  mostly  consmned 
by  a  local  rolling  mill,  and  one  at  Tacoma,  Wash.,  which  refines  copper 
primarily  on  toll  for  the  foreign  trade.  On  the  copper  coming  into 
the  Connecticut  Valley  from  refineries  other  than  those"  located  in  the 
New  York  area,  prices  are  arrived  at  by  adding  freight  and  interest 
from  the  New  York  basing  point. 

A  number  of  years  ago  there  is  said  to  have  been  an  exception  to  the 
practice  of  adding  freight  and  interest  charges  to  f.  o.  b.  New  York 
prices  in  arriving  at  delivered  prices.  Delivery  was  made  in  the 
general  area  sm-rounding  the  refineries  free  of  charge,  and  transporta- 
tion was  included  only  when  the  freight  costs  amounted  to  a  sub- 
stantial figure.  Whether  or  not  this  practice  still  prevails  is  not 
known. 

The  practice  of  selling  refined  virgin  copper  f.  o.  b.  New  York  basing 
point  has  generally  been  imitated  in  the  sale  of  secondary  copper. 
Secondary  copper  is  produced  by  collecting  and  remelting  scrap 
copper  and  is  not  as  pure  a  product  as  refined  copper.  However,  it  is 
•directly  competitive  with  virgin  copper  in  the  manufacture  of  brd,ss, 
for  which  purpose  minor  impurities  are  not  objectionable,  and  is  sold 
delivered  at  the  Connecticut  Valley  on  the  basis  of  the  f.  o.  b.  New 
York  price  for  virgin  copper  plus  transportation  and  interest  charges. 
The  price  for  secondary  copper  is  largely  influenced  by  trading  in  the 
organized  futures  market  in  NeW  York  City. 

While  the  refineries  are  highly  concentrated  in  the  vicinity  of  New 
York,  the  remelting  plants  are  widely  scattered  over  the  country. 
For  that  reason,  freight  absorption  is  typical  or  general  in  the  sale 
of  secondary  copper  while,  because  of  the  high  concentration  of  re- 
fineries in  the  New  York  area,  it  is  exceptional  in  the  case  of  refined 
or  virgin  electrolytic  copper.  Consequently  net  realizations  to  the 
seller  on  secondary  copper  vary  widely,  depending  on  the  location  of 
the  remelting  plants,  while  realizations  in  the  case  of  refined  copper 
are  generally  uniform. 

Lake  copper. — Lake  copper  is  found  in  the  natural  state  in  the  form 
of  the  metal  rather  than  the  ore,  and  its  production  involves  separation 
rather  than  a  refining  process.  It  is  produced  mainly  in  Michigan 
and  consumed  principally  in  the  Detroit  area.  It  represents  only 
about  15  percent  of  the  total  copper  produced  in  the  United  States. 
While  the  geographic  price  structure  for  lake  copper  has  not  been 
definitely  ascertained,  it  clearly  differs  from  that  of  the  electrolytic 
metal.  Price  quotations  for  lake  copper  delivered  in  the  Midwest  are 
the  same  as  for  delivery  in  the  Connecticut  Valley,  while  electrolytic 
copper  is  0.125  cent  higher  in  the  former  than  in  the  latter  area  because 
of  the  difference  in  freight  from  the  New  York  base.  As  a  result,  lake 
copper  and  electrolytic  copper  are  quoted  at  the  same  level  in  the 
Connecticut  Valley,  but  the  price  of  lake  copper  is  slightly  lower 
than  that  of  the  electrolytic  in  the  Midwest. 

Scrap  metalJ^ — Scrap  metal  is  an  important  factor  in  most  metal 
markets.  Prices  for  scrap  metal,  however,  are  apparently  quoted  by 
buyers  rather  than  by  sellers,  presumably  because  the  former  are  in  a 
stronger  economic  position  and  can  exercise  an  important  direct 
influence  upon  the  market.  Prices  for  scrap  are  quoted  in  the  Daily 
Metal  Trade  on  the  following  basis: 

"  Nonferrous  metals. 


I 
I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  341 

In  lots  of  100  pounds  or  more,  order  basis,  f.  o.  b.  point  of  shipment.  Actual 
freight  allowed  not  exceeding  $1  per  hundredweight  for  complete  shipment  at  any 
time  on  an  order  basis  in  lots  of  100  pounds  net  or  more.  Additional  one-half 
cent  per  pound  allowance  for  shipment  of  10,000  pounds  or  more  at  one  time. 

The  result  of  this  form  of  quotation  may  be  to  equalize  the  bids  of 
competing  buyers  at  the  point  of  shipment  and  thus  to  prevent  prices 
from  being  raised  by  competition  for  supplies. 

PETROLEUM  AND  ITS  PRODUCTS 

The  geographic  price  structure  for  petroleum  and  its  products  is 
not  as  well  defined  nor  adhered  to  as  that  for  most  of  the  other  non- 
agricultural  commodities  which  have  been  described.  Constantly 
changing  competitive  conditions  due  partly  to  the  frequent  discovery 
of  new  producing  fields  probably  prevents  practice  from  crystallizing. 

In  general,  crude  oil  is  sold  f.  o.  b.  producing  field,  while  gasoline  is 
usually  quoted  on  a  delivered  basis.  Methods  of  marketing  these 
products  were  described  in  detail  at  hearings  before  the  Temporary 
National  Economic  Committee  held  during  October  1939,  and  conse- 
quently only  the  outstanding  characteristics  of  these  practices  will  be 
described  here. 

Crude  oil. — Prices  for  crude  oil  at  each  field  are  nominally  based 
upon  a  "posted"  price  set  by  one  or  more  purchasers.  The  number  of 
refiners  obtaining  crude  oil  from  any  one  field  is  usually  quite  limited, 
and  some  one  of  these  commonly  acts  as  the  leader  in  posting  prices, 
or  as  a  witness  for  the  industry  phrased  it,  "the  interpreter  of  market 
conditions."  ^*  According  to  the  same  witness  this  posted  price  is 
said  to  reflect  "so  far  as  competitive  conditions  will  permit,  the  relative 
value  of  the  crude  at  the  refinery."  "  Of  course,  competition  for 
supplies  between  differently  located  refiners  is  an  important  factor  in 
determining  the  posted  price  in  any  field  and  the  system  itself,  insofar 
as  it  is  adhered  to,  may  have  some  effect  in  preventing  prices  from 
being  "bid  up"  by  this  kind  of  competition  between  buyers. 

Although  prices  posted  by  all  refiners  in  any  single  field  at  any  one 
time  for  oU  of  a  designated  specific  gravity  are  usually  identical,  this 
does  not  mean  that  all  transactions  take  place  at  this  price.  If  the 
market  is  weak  some  sales  will  be  made  at  a  discount;  if  the  market 
is  strong  some  oil  may  move  at  a  premium.  Of  course,  when  the 
posted  price  comes  to  be  honored  in  the  breach  more  than  in  the 
observance  it  is  adjusted,  and  over  any  long  period  of  time  it  is  prob- 
able that  the  bulk  of  crude  oil  moves  at  the  posted  price  level.  Accord- 
ing to  one  witness  for  the  industry,  "at  times  as  much  as  20  percent, 
at  Umes  practically  none"  is  sold  at  levels  below  the  posted  price.^* 

Gasoline. — The  geographic  price  structure  for  gasoline  varies  in  dif- 
ferent sections  of  the  country.  There  are  10  basic  refining  districts 
in  the  United  States,  of  which  3,  the  Gulf  (including  the  Louisiana 
and  Texas  refining  districts),  "group  3"  (comprising  primarily  Okla- 
homa, Texas,  and  Missouri),  and  the  Pacific  coast,  are  the  most  impor- 
tant. Of  these  the  Gulf  district  shipping  by  water,  supplies  most  of 
the  Atlantic  seaboard.  "Group  3"  governs  prices  through  much  of 
the  Midwest,  and  the  Pacific  coast  supplies  part  of  the  Rocky  Moun- 

'•  See  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  Hearings,  Part  17,  p.  0845. 

"  Ibid,  p.  9944. 

'•  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  Hearings,  Part  15,  p.  8358. 


342  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

tain  area  in  addition  to  the  west  coast.  There  is  some  competition 
between  these  districts  in  border  areas,  in  which  gasoline  from  different 
som-ces  meets;  thus  parts  of  Ohio  may  be  served  by  the  Gulf  district 
via  the  east  coast  as  well  as  by  the  "group  3"  refineries.  In  addition 
minor  refining  districts  affect  the  price  structure  in  many  sections ;  this 
is  true,  for  example,  of  the  Appalachian  area  in  Pennsylvania,  of  the 
Illinois  area,  etc. 

Quotations  for  each  of  these  refinery  districts  are  published  daily  in 
Piatt's  OHgram  and  usually  indicate  a  range  of  prices  obtained  from 
a  number  of  buyers  and  sellers. 

In  most  districts  other  than  "group  3"  delivered  prices  vary  with 
shipping  costs  from  the  refinery,  subject,  however,  to  a  great  deal  of 
unsystematic  freight  equalization  to  meet  competition.  For  example, 
some  of  the  Gulf  crude  oil  is  refined  along  the  Gulf  and  shipped  as 
gasoline  at  Atlantic  ports,  but  some  is  transported  in  the  form  of 
petroleum  to  be  refined  at  various  points  along  the  eastern  seaboard. 
Gasoline  for  sale  at  inland  destinations  accessible  to  more  than  one 
seaport  may,  therefore,  proceed  along  various  routes  and  competition 
is  likely  to  be  reflected  in  a  certain  amount  of  unsystematic  freight 
absorption  or  equahzation. 

In  "group  3"  area,  the  nominal  price  structure  is  based  upon  all  rail 
freight  from  a  single  basing  point  at  Tulsa,  Oklahoma.  The  develop- 
ment of  this  structure  may  be  traced  to  the  fact  that  the  raU  freight  rate 
schedules  in  this  area,  known  as  the  "group  3"  rates,  are  such  that 
transportation  charges  to  any  given  destination  in  the  Midwest  are 
the  same  from  any  point  of  origin  in  the  midcontinent  producing  area. 
The  delivered  price  at  any  destination,  therefore,  will  be  the  Tulsa 
price  as  reported  in  Piatt's  Oilgram  plus  all  rail  freight  from  Tulsa. 
Insofar  as  shipments  are  actually  made  by  rail  and  in  the  form  of 
gasoline,  this  result  does  not  differ  from  what  would  have  been  obtained 
if  the  quotation  were  f.  o.  b.  refinery.  However,  there  are  two  addi- 
tional means  of  transportation  available,  shipment  of  gasoline  from 
refineries  in  the  midcontinent  district  by  pipe  line  to  destination,  and 
transportation  of  the  crude  oil  from  this  district  by  pipe  line  to  refin- 
eries in  consummg  areas.  Both  of  these  methods  of  transportation 
are  cheaper  than  all  rail  freight  and  neither  is  reflected  in  the  nominal 
delivered  price  structure.  Consequently  the  "Tulsa  plus"  practice  in 
the  "group  3"  territory,  to  the  extent  to  which  it  is  observed,  can 
properly  be  described  as  a  single  basing  point. 

Increasing  difficulty  is  apparently  being  encountered  in  maintaining 
this  price  structure  in  the  "group  3"  area,  primarily  because  of  the 
development  of  new  oil  fields  in  Illinois,  Michigan,  and  elsewhere. 
For  this  reason  the  practice  described  is  probably  subject  to  substan- 
tially more  variation  than  is  true  for  such  products  as  steel  or  cement. 

BITUMINOUS   COAL 

The  market  for  bituminous  coal  is  extremely  complex.  In  any  given 
consuming  center,  there  may  be  competition  among  many  different 
varieties  of  coal  coming  from  different  mines  and  shipped  by  different 
means  of  transpol-tation.  In  many  cities  shipments  may  be  received 
by  rail,  truck,  and  water.  Because  of  the  extremely  keen  character  of 
competition,  producers  have  generally  been  willing  to  grant  whatever 


I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  343 

concessions  were  necessary  to  make  sales.  The  result  can  best  be 
described  as  an  extremely  unsystematic  process  of  freight  equalization. 
The  Bituminous  Coal  Division,  in  estabUshing  TniniTnuTn  prices 
under  the  provisions  of  the  Bituminous  Coal  Act  of  1937,  has  largely 
recognized  prevailing  practice.  Price  schedules  at  each  mine  often 
include  differentials  depending  upon  both  the  destiaation  and  the 
method  of  shipment,  and  an  effort  has  been  made  by  means  of  these 
differentials  to  equalize  destination  prices  for  similar  or  competing 
fuels. 

SUMMARY EXTENT  OF  MAJOR  TYPES  OF  GEOGRAPHIC  PRICE  STRUCTURE 

The  descriptions  of  the  geographic  price  structures  of  specific 
products  and  groups  of  products  which  have  been  presented  in  this 
chapter  indicate  that  many  of  them  do  not  fall  into  any  simple  pattern. 
Any  method  of  classification  is  necessarily  arbitrary  and  must  ignore 
many  significant  variations  of  practice.  Nevertheless,  an  attempt  has 
been  made  to  indicate  the  extent  to  which  the  outstanding  major  types 
of  geographic  price  structure  have  been  encountered  in  the  course  of 
this  analysis. 

Uniform  f.  0.  b.  plant  pricing. — Uniform  f.  o.  b.  plant  pricing  subject 
to  minor  variations  is  characteristic  of  the  following  kinds  of 
commodities: 

1 .  The  products  of  light  consumer  goods  manufacturing  industries, 
particularly  when  sold  with  emphasis  upon  trade-marks  or  brand 
names,  including  textile  yarns,  gray  goods,  and  cloth,  except  rayon 
yam;  apparel;  leather  and  leather  footwear;  certain  staple  food  items 
such  as  wheat  flour;  bulk  chese;  canned  and  dried  fruits;  canned  to- 
matoes; lard;  black  pepper.  Other  prepared  foods  when  sold  in  bulk 
or  under  distributor's  or  unadvertised  labels,  including  corn  meal; 
crackers;  chocolate  coating;  rice;  cocoa;  coffee;  tea;  creamery  butter; 
processed  cheese;  canned  soup;  canned  vegetables;  canned  salmon; 
vinegar;  vegetable  shortening.  Certain  standard  drug  items  sold 
under  their  chemical  names,  such  as  dextrose,  cocaine,  ether,  etc. 

2.  Some  unstandardized  products  in  which  competition  is  primarily 
on  a  nonprice  basis:   Household  furniture;  some  industrial  machinery. 

3.  Certain  items  whose  production  is  confined  within  a  narrow 
geographic  area:  Phosphate  rock;  superphosphate;  turpentine; 
Philippine  mahogany  (sold  f.  o.  b.  its  main  port  of  entry). 

4.  Some  industrial  raw  materials  in  which  the  price  structure  is 
largely  controlled  by  buyers:  Nonferrous  scrap  metal;  cottonseed 
(at  least  until  1934). 

5.  Automobiles,  though  the  structure  has  some  of  the  elements  of  a 
basing  point  system. 

6.  Agricultural  implements,  subject  to  occasional  freight  equaliza- 
tion. 

7.  Lake  Superior  iron  ore  (f.  o.  b.  lower  lake  ports). 

8.  Imported  iron  ores  (f.  o.  b.  ports). 

Uniform  delivered  prices. — In  most  cases  the  term  "uniform  delivered 
price"  applies  to  delivery  at  railroad  destination,  but  it  may  also 
include  delivery  to  the  plant  warehouse  or  retail  outlet  of  the  buyer. 
All  types  of  pricing  practice  which  arrive  at  this  result  have  been 
included  in  this  category,  whether  they  take  the  form  of  a  delivered 

247149 — 4] — No.  1 24 


344  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

price  quotation,  a  price  f.  o.  b.  destination,  or  a  price  f.  o.  b.  shipping 
point  with  freight  allowed  or  prepaid. 

Uniform  delivered  prices  throughout  the  United  States,  subject  to 
minor  modifications,  have  been  observed  for  the  following  kinds  of 
products : 

1.  Many  light  consumer  goods  sold  under  nationally  advertised 
manufacturers'  brands,  particularly  where  the  manufacturer  makes 
some  effort  to  control  resale  price:  Branded  drugs,  toiletries,  and  cos- 
metics; cigarettes,  cigars,  and  smoking  tobacco.  Many  nationally 
advertised  branded  foods  and  groceries,  including  coffee,  vegetable 
shortening,  ginger  ale  and  club  soda,  grape  juice,  corn  flakes,  wheat 
cereal,  crackers,  macaroni  (also  private  brands),  pretzels  (also  bulk), 
condensed  milk  (also  private  brands),  powdered  milk,  soap  (toilet, 
laundry,  and  flakes — also  private  brands),  canned  soup,  canned  vege- 
tables (some  brands),  jelly  (some  manufacturers'  brands,  also  private 
brands),  molasses  (some  brands,  also  bulk),  oleomargarine  (also  pri- 
vate brands),  peanut  butter  (some  private  brands),  tea,  vinegar  (some 
manufacturers'  brands,  also  private  brands). 

2.  A  limited  number  of  additional  products,  usually  in  cases  where 
freight  is  a  relatively  minor  item  in  the  delivered  price:  Most  hard- 
ware, tools,  and  other  light  fabricated  steel;  most  electrical  machinery; 
electric  fans  and  vacuum  cleaners;  business  machines,  such  as  type- 
writers; insulation  board;  plumbing  fixtures;  aluminum;  electrolytic 
zinc;  rayon  yam;  manila  rope;  leather  transmission  belting;  mahogany; 
many  planing-mill  products.  Some  chemicals,  usually  with  relatively 
high  value  per  unit  of  weight,  e.  g.,  butyl  acetate;  coal-tar  dyes. 

Zone  delivered  prices.—  The  following  products  are  sold  on  a  zone 
basis  with  delivered  prices  generally  uniform  within  each  i:.one: 

1.  Some  food  products,  including  corn  flakes,  farina,  and  oatmeal; 
bulk  powdered  milk;  evaporated  milk;  vegetable  oil;  processed  cheese 
(nationally  advertised);  rice  (nationally  advertised);  some  brands  of 
baked  beans;  jelly  (some  brands);  molasses  (some  brands);  peanut 
butter  (some  brands);  packaged  starch;  packaged  sirup  in  some  areas. 

2.  Paper  and  most  paper  products. 

3.  Snuff. 

4.  Mixed  fertilizer. 

5.  Some  chemicals:  Synthetic  methanol;  carbon  tetrachloride  (ex- 
cept Pacific  and  Mountain  States);  carbon  black;  industrial  benzol 
(east  of  Omaha) ;  cyanamid ;  hydrochloric  acid,  soda  ash,  and  sodium 
hydroxide  (in  1.  c.  1.  lots  only);  flake  calcium  chloride. 

6.  Some  building  materials:  Linseed  oil,  prepared  paints  (national 
brands),  white  lead,  doors,  windows  and  window  frames. 

7.  Business  furniture. 

8.  Some  electrical  machinery. 

9.  Electrical  household  equipment:  Refrigerators  (sales  to  retailers 
and  consumers  only);  washing  machines;  electric  ranges. 

Freight  equalization. — The  following  list  of  products  comprises  those 
in  the  sale  of  which  freight  equalization  is  systematically  or  at  least 
r^ularly  practiced.  In  addition,  it  should  be  remembered,  sporadic 
freight  absorption  to  meet  competition  occurs  in  many  markets  in 
which  some  other  form  of  geographic  price  structure  is  dominant: 

1.  Salt. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  345 

2.  Many  building  materials:  Lime;  floor  tile;  sewer  pipe;  gypsum 
plaster;  prepared  roofing;  window  glass;  heating  boilers  and  radiation. 

3.  Binder  twine. 

4.  Many  heavy  chemicals,  e.  g.,  sulfuric  acid;  sodium  bichromate; 
tribasic  calcium  phosphate;  aluminum  sulfate;  soda  ash;  sodium 
hydroxide;  sodium  silicate;  hydrochloric  acid;  anhydrous  ammonia; 
sodium  bicarbonate;  calcium  carbide;  hydrogen  peroxide;  tribasic 
sodium  phosphate;  nitrocellulose;  acetic  acid  (except  seaboard 
states). 

5.  TJnsystematic  freight  equalization  occurs  in  the  sale  of:  Much 
industrial  machinery;  Douglas  fir;  Ponderosa  pine;  gasoline;  bitu- 
minous coal. 

Basing  point  industries. — The  following  products  are  sold  in  ac- 
cordance with  a  single  basing-point  system:  Maple  flooring;  zinc 
(except  electrolytic);  copper  (except  lake  copper);  industrial  benzol 
(region  Omaha  and  west);  gasoline  (group  3  district,  subject  to 
considerable  variation). 

Multiple  basing  points. — Multiple  basing  points  are  observed  in  the 
following  industries:  Cement;  pulp;  southern  pine  (subject  to  con- 
siderable variation);  oak  flooring;  lead;  steel;  muriate  of  potash; 
sugar. 

Local  markets. — The  markets  for  some  products  are  so  purely  local 
that  no  geographic  price  structure  in  the  ordinary  sense  can  be  said 
to  exist.  Outstanding  examples  of  this  situation  are:  Brick;  sand 
and  gravel;  building  tile;  bread. 

Unsystematic  variation. — In  the  case  of  some  products,  delivered 
prices  are  so  largely  determined  by  local  conditions,  that  there  is  no 
systematic  pattern  of  variation.  This  is  true  of:  Most  agricultural 
commodities;  meats. 


PART  III 

PRICES  AND  PRICE  MARGINS  IN  THE 
DRUG  TRADE 

BY 

SAUL  NELSON  and  LAURA  MAE  BROWN 

ASSISTED  BY 

BERNICE  M.  MONTGOMERY 


PART  III 
PREFACE 

Retail  prices  are  of  primary  importance  to  the  economy.  It  is 
the  price  charged  to  the  consimier  which,  in  the  last  analysis,  deter- 
mines his  standard  of  living  and  his  purchasing  power;  that  is,  the 
amount  and  variety  of  goods  and  services  which  he  is  able  to  buy  on 
the  market.  It  is  the  consumer's  purchasing  power  which,  in  turn, 
governs  the  demand  for  labor  and  material  resources  used  in  production 
of  the  goods  produced  by  this  great  sector  of  the  economy.  It  was 
pointed  out  in  part  I  of  this  volume  that  most  recent  studies  of  prices 
have  concentrated  largely  upon  prices  in  wholesale  markets  and  have 
accorded  insufficient  emphasis  to  the  importance  of  retail  prices. 

Part  III  is  concerned  with  the  behavior  of  retail  prices  and  with 
the  price  spread  between  wholesale  and  retail  markets  in  one  selected 
field — drugs,  toiletries,  and  drug  sundries.  The  bulk  of  these  products 
is  sold  by  retail  druggists.  They  are  of  particular  interest  at  the  pre- 
sent time  because  they  afford  the  outstanding  illustration  of  the  eriect 
of  resale  price  maintenance  legislation  upon  retail  prices  and  distribu- 
tive margins.  Some  of  the  economic  implications  of  this  legislation 
have  been  discussed  in  part  I  of  this  volume.  Part  III  makes  no 
further  appraisal,  but  merely  presents  factual  data  which  may  serve  as 
a  guide  to  poUcy. 

Part  III  consists  of  three  chapters.  The  first  is  a  brief  description 
of  some  of  the  saUent  characteristics  of  the  market  for  products 
handled  by  the  drug  trade.  It  points  out  that  competition  in  the  sale 
of  these  products  has  for  a  number  of  reasons  emphasized  con- 
siderations other  than  price,  such  as  brand  names,  advertising,  quality, 
fancy  packaging,  and  service,  and  describes  some  of  the  rnethods  used 
by  manufacturers  to  control  retail  prices  and  distributive  margins, 
including  particularly  the  so-called  Fair  Trade  Acts. 

Chapter  II  discusses  various  characteristics  of  the  retail  price 
behavior  of  these  products ;  in  particular  the  trend  of  retail  prices 
over  a  period  of  years  and  the  effect  of  resale  price  maintenance 
legislation  upon  this  trend,  the  extent  to  which  retail  prices  vary 
between  different  stores,  and  comparative  prices  of  nationally  adver- 
tised merchandise  and  of  similar  products  sold  under  less  well  known  or 
private  labels. 

Chapter  III  presents  data  regarding  the  distributive  margins  or 
mark-ups  obtained  by  wholesalers  and  retailers  on  the  sale  of  these 
articles  and  describes  the  price  structures  for  a  few  selected  items 
in  some  detail.  This  is  followed  by  a  more  general  sunmiary  of  mar- 
gins for  a  wide  variety  of  products. 

The  retail  price  data  presented  in  this  study  are  based  largely  upon 
the  records  of  the  Retail  Price  Division  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor 
Statistics.     Some  unpublished  information  regarding  retail  prices  in 

349 


25Q  CONCBl^TBATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

one  city — Columbus,  Ohio — was  also  made  available  by  the  Marketing 
Laws  Survey  of  the  Works  Progress  Administration.  The  information 
regarding  wholesale  prices  and  distributive  margins  was  obtained 
through  the  helpful  cooperation  of  various  members  of  the  industry, 
including  both  manufacturers  and  wholesalers.  Mr.  Wroe  AJderson,  of 
the  Curtis  PublisLmg  Co.,  rendered  material  help  in  the  planning  of 
this  study. 

Part  III  was  prepared  by  Saul  Nelson  and  Laura  Mae  Brown. 
Bemice  M.  Montgomery  compiled  information  regarding  marketing 
and  pricing  pohcies  and  price  margins  and  assisted  in  preparing  the 
report. 


CHAPTER  I 
GENERAL  CHARACTERISTICS  OF  THE  MARKET 

The  retail  market  for  products  handled  by  the  drug  trade— drugs, 
toiletries  and  sundries — is  in  many  respects  a  peculiar  market,  be- 
cause of  the  nature  of  the  product,  the  way  in  which  the  industry  is 
organized,  and  the  operation  of  Federal  and  State  laws  which  govern 
competitive  relations.  The  very  nature  of  drug  products  makes  it 
peculiariy  diflBcult  for  the  average  consumer  to  appraise  their  merits 
objectively.  Of  course,  problems  of  selection  exist  to  a  greater  or  less 
extent  in  the  purchase  of  most  consumers'  goods,  but  in  the  case  of 
drugs  these  difficulties  are  many  times  multiplied.  Thus,  while  the 
initial  choice  between  two  alternative  makes  of,  say,  canned  corn  or 
clothing  may  be  difficult,  the  consumer  can  and  does  experiment  and 
judges  by  his  experience.  The  taste  of  food  products  or  the  wearing 
quahties  of  apparel  are  not  beyond  the  capacity  of  the  average  con- 
sumer to  measure.  In  the  case  of  drugs,  however,  experimentation 
is  much  less  feasible  and  sometimes  even  dangerous.  The  physio- 
logical effect  of  a  drug  is  exceedingly  difficult  for  the  user  to  appraise 
and  even  repeated  use  affords  no  basis  for  judgment  as  to  efficacy. 
Moreover,  most  buyers  are  probably  completely  unaware  of  the  stand- 
ards established  in  the  United  States  Pharmacopoeia,  and  the  letters 
U.  S.  P.  mean  little  or  nothing  to,  him. 

The  inability  of  the  average  consumer  to  compare  products  in- 
telligently on  a  price  basis  has  diverted  competition  between  rival 
products  largely  to  other  things  than  price,  such  as  advertising, 
packaging,  attractive  flavor  or  odor  and  the  offer  of  inducements  to 
distributors  to  stock  and  push  merchandise.  Within  limits,  a  low 
price  may  even  prove  to  be  a  competitive  disadvantage,  particularly 
if  it  is  considerably  lower  than  the  level  prevailing  for  similar  mer- 
chandise, since  some  consumers  may  associate  an  unusually  low  price 
with  poor  quality.  It  is  sometimes  possible  to  sell  more  drugs  or 
cosmetics  at  a  price  which  is  at  or  only  slightly  below  the  prevailing 
level  for  similar  merchandise  than  it  would  be  at  prices  materially 
below  that  level. 

The  experience  of  one  large  drug  chain  illustrates  this  point.  A  few 
years  ago  this  organization  placed  its  own  private  brand  of  aspirin  on 
the  market  at  the  price  of  19  cents  a  hundred  tablets.  The  prevailing 
price  for  the  best  known  manufacturer's  bran(^  of  aspirin  ranged  from 
59  cents  to  75  cents  a  himdred  tablets.  This  very  wide  differential 
in  price  apparently  created  suspicion  among  consumers  with  regard  to 
the  merits  of  the  chaiu-store  brand.  As  a  result  volume  failed  to  reach 
a  satisfactory  level.  This  suggested  new  tactics,  and  the  price  was 
raised  from  19  cents  to  49  cents.  Consumers  then  began  to  accept  it, 
appearing  to  decide  that  it  afforded  a  legitimate  opportunity  to  econ- 
omize without  any  sacrifice  in  quality.  Volume  soon  expanded  to  a 
profitable  level. 

351 


352  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Consequently,  in  purchasing  drugs  and  similar  products,  the  con- 
sumer is  forced  to  rely  largely  upon  advertising  claims,  or  upon  the 
advice  of  his  physician  or  druggist.  Mere  excellence  of  a  product  will 
not  find  it  a  market  unless  some  forms  of  sales  assistance  can  be  en- 
listed. Some  of  the  results  of  this  competitive  situation  have  been 
described  in  part  I  of  this  volume.^  Wide  differences  occur  between 
the  prices  of  drug  products  which  are  virtually  or  abolutely  identical, 
and  retail  "prices  often  bear  little  if  any  recognizable  relationship  to 
the  physical  cost  of  production. 

Moreover,  the  drug  store  itself  differs  in  a  number  of  respects 
from  most  other  retail  stores.  At  least  some  of  its  sales  clerks  must 
conform  to  certain  standards  of  professional  competency.  In  the 
case  of  most  independent  drug  stores  the  proprietor  is  himself  a 
registered  pharmacist.  In  fact,  many  pharmacists  think  of  themselves 
as  professional  practitioners  first  and  as  retail  merchants  second; 
they  believe  consciously  or  unconsciously  that  they  are  entitled  to  a 
greater  measure  of  protection  in  the  conduct  of  their  trade  than  would 
be  justified  for  mere  lay  retailers.  The  consumer,  moreover,  usually 
attributes  considerably  more  weight  to  the  advice  of  a  pharmacist 
concerning  his  purchase  of  drug-store  products  than  he  would  to  that 
of,  say,  a  grocery  clerk,  regarding  the  merits  of  various  food  products. 
All  this  serves  to  emphasize  the  nonprice  aspects  of  competition. 

Another  distinct  characteristic  of  the  drug  trade  which  affects 
operating  costs  is  the  exceptionally  large  number  of  different  indi- 
vidual items  handled.  For  example,  a  survey  conducted  by  the  De- 
partment of  Commerce  showed  that  6,  out  of  a  total  of  7  independent 
drug  stores  studied,  carried  between  4,500  and  8,200  distinct  items.^ 
As  a  result,  the  turn-over  of  individual  products  is  slow  and,  for  the 
same  reason,  the  independent  retailer  frequently  purchases  in  very 
small  lots.  Thus  he  will  often  buy  only  one  or  two  packages  of  each 
item  at  any  one  time  from  his  supplier,  although  in  order  to  give 
such  dealings  the  dignity  of  wholesale  transactions,  they  are  usually 
referred  to  as  "1/12  of  a  dozen  lots"  or  "1/6  of  a  dozen  lots."  The 
only  possible  effect  of  such  a  situation  is  to  raise  wholesale  and  retail 
operating  costs  and  necessitate  wider  distributive  margins. 

RESALE    PRICE    CONTROLS 

Manufacturers  of  branded  drugs,  toiletries,  and  cosmetics,  and 
trade-mark  owners  other  than  manufacturers,  have  long  sought  to 
exercise  some  degree  of  control  over  the  price  at  which  products 
bearing  their  labels  were  resold  on  the  retail  market.  The  reasons 
for  this  pohcy  have  been  considered  in  part  I  of  this  volume  ^  and  will 
not  be  repeated  here  in  detail.  It  is  sufficient  for  the  present  purpose 
to  suggest  what  is  probably  the  naost  important  of  these  reasons — 
the  desire  to  maintain  retail  prices  at  a  level  which  would  yield  the 
druggist  a  margin  sufficient  to  enlist  his  active  sales  cooperation. 
The  so-called  fair-trade  laws,  which  at  present  afford  a  very  effective 
means  of  maintaining  retail  prices,  will  be  described  subsequently. 

The  degree  and  manner  of  control  exercised  by  trade-mark  owners 
over  retail  prices  varies  considerably.     One  practice  commonly  utilized 

>  See  supra,  pp.  80-83. 

'Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce,  Domestic  Commerce  Series  No.  90.  Cost,  Sales,  and  Profits 
in  the  Retail  Drug  Store,  table  36,  pp.  IlO-lll. 
»  See  sapra,  pp.  60-62,  89-90. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  353 

is  the  establishment  of  a  list  price,  which  may  or  may  not  be  actually 
printed  on  the  package.  This  list  price  is  usually  set  at  even  figures 
(e.  g.,  25  cents,  50  cents,  $1).  Its  significance  differs  considerably;  in 
some  cases  it  is  desired  or  anticipated  that  the  Hst  price  should  be  the 
actual  level  at  which  most  transactions  take  place,  in  others  it  is 
intended  to  constitute  httle  more  than  a  nominal  quotation  and  there 
is  no  objection  upon  the  part  of  the  trade-mark  owner  to  moderate 
reductions  below  list.  In  either  case  a  list  price,  particularly  if  it  is 
actually  printed  on  the  package,  usually  constitutes  an  effective 
ceiling  to  prices,  since  consumers  will  rarely  be  willing  to  pay  more 
than  the  amount  specified.  Although  the  use  of  a  list  price  is  cus- 
tomary, it  is  by  no  means  universal.  Thus,  according  to  a  study  by 
the  United  States  Department  of  Commerce: 

Out  of  46  commodity  groups  studied,  there  are  15  on  which  list  prices  are 
seldom  shown.  *  *  *  These  are  after-shaving  lotions,  baby  powders,  dental- 
plate  brushes,  dusting  powder,  disinfectants,  eye  medicines,  face  creams,  face 
powders,  hairbrushes,  finger-nail  preparations,  plasters,  shampoos,  skin  lotions, 
talcum  powders,  and  sanitary  napkins.^ 

In  addition  to,  ©r  in  place  of  a  list  price,  many  trade-mark  owners 
also  seek  to  establish  a  definite  minimum  below  which  their  product 
is  under  no  circumstances  to  be  sold  at  retail.  Where  there  is  both 
a  list  and  a  minimum,  the  relation  between  the  two  varies.  In  some 
cases  the  minimum  may  be  estabhshed  at  the  full  hst,  in  others  it 
may  be  1  or  2  cents  imder  list,  and,  in  still  others,  it  may  be  as  much 
as  20  to  25  percent  below  list. 

Until  recently,  trade-mark  owners  had  no  legal  means  of  requiring 
the  observance  of  such  minimum  prices.  In  fact,  in  1911  a  Supreme 
Court  decision  ruled  that  any  contract  between  a  manufacturer  and 
his  distributors  providing  for  the  maintenance  of  minimum  resale 
prices  was  a  violation  of  the  antitrust  laws.*  For  the  next  20  years 
the.  only  method  trade-mark  owners  could  lawfully  adopt  in  order 
to  maintain  minimum  resale  prices  for  their  products  was  to  refuse 
t9  sell  to  distributors  of  whose  sales  poUcy  thgy  disapproved.  More- 
over, such  "refusal  to  sell"  could  only  be  practiced  within  certain 
limits  which  impaired  its  effectiveness.  Detailed  supervision  of  dis- 
tributors' sales  poHcies  was  held  illegal.® 

Two  major  changes  in  this  situation  occurred  during  the  last  decade. 
One  of  these  was  only  of  temporary  duration;  the  National  Re- 
covery Administration  code  for  the  retail  drug  trade  contained  a 
provision  which  imposed  certain  limits  upon  price  cutting.  The 
second  and  more  lasting  change  has  been  the  enactment  of  state  laws 
permitting  trade-mark  owners  to  contract  with  their  distributors  for 
the  maintenance  of  minimum  resale  prices  and  making  the  provisions 
of  such  contracts  binding  even  upon  distributors  who  are  not  parties 
to  the  contract. 

Although  the  first  law  of  this  kind  was  passed  by  California  in  1933, 
their  effectiveness  really  dates  only  from  December  7,  1936,  when  the 
United  States  Supreme  Court  upheld  their  constitutionality.^  These 
decisions  greatly  stimulated  the  drive  by  retail  druggists  for  the  enact- 

•  Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce,  Domestic  Commerce  Series  No.  73,  Merchandising  Re- 
quirements of  the  Drug  Store  Package,  p.  10. 

•  Dt.  Mil's  Medical  Company  v.  Parka  and  Sons  (220  U.  S.  373). 

•  Federal  frade  Commission  v.  Beech-Nut  Packing  Co.  (257  U.  S.  441);  and  Standard  Fashion  Co.  v.  Magrane 
Houston  Co.  (258  U.  S.  346  (1921)). 

'  Pep  Boys,  Manny,  Moe,  and  Jack,  of  California  v.  Pj/royl  Sales  Company,  Inc.:  Kunsman  v.  Max  Factor 
ond  Company,  et  al.  (299  U.  S.  198). 


354         CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

ment  of  similar  legislation  in  other  States.  As  of  June  1940,  resale 
price  maintenance  was  pernussible  in  44  States,  excluding  onlj  Texas, 
Missouri,  Vermont,  Delaware,  and  the  District  of  Columbia.  The 
Federal  Miller-Tydings  Act,  which  was  enacted  on  August  17,  1937, 
exempts  resale  price  maintenance  contracts  in  interstate  commerce 
from  the  prohibitions  of  the  antitrust  laws. 

The  enactment  of  this  legislation  and  the  issuance  of  price  main- 
tenance contracts  under  its  provisions  by  most  leading  manufacturers 
of  products  handled  by  the  drug  trade  nas  had  a  very  marked  effect 
upon  the  pattern  of  retail  prices  for  the  commodities  affected.  The 
nature  of  this  effect  will  be  apparent  from  an  examination  of  the  data 
presented  later  in  this  chapter. 

Before  proceeding  to  an  examination  of  these  data,  however,  it  is 
useful  to  consider  briefly  the  significance  of  brand  names  and  the  vary- 
ing competitive  relationships  between  different  kinds  of  drug  products. 
At  least  three  distinct  situations  exist : 

(1)  Ther^  is  a  wide  variety  of  standard  drugs  such  as  milk  of  mag- 
nesia, aspirin,  etc.,  which  are  regularly  sold  under  those  designations, 
but  which  carry  also  the  advertised  labels  of  their  maker  (e.  g., 
Bayer's  Aspirin,  Squibb's  Castor  Oil,  Phillips'  Milk  of  Magnesia,  etc.). 
There  may  be  considerable  differences  in  the  manner  of  packaging  or 
compounding,  but  in  the  main,  the  active  ingredients  of  these  products 
are  identical  and  their  composition  is  as  specified  in  the  United  States 
Pharmacopoeia. 

(2)  A  second  group  of  items  is  sold  alternately  imder  names  recog- 
nized in  the  pharmacopoeia  and  under  proprietary  designations.  For 
example,  the  standard  hypnotic  known  as  barbital  may  also  be  pur- 
chased under  the  proprietary  designation  Veronal;  Phenacetin  is  the 
proprietary  name  for  a  brand  of  acetophenetidin;  Aristol-Winthrop 
is  a  brand  of  thymol-iodide,  etc.  In  a  case  of  this  sort,  a  product 
sold  under  the  proprietary  name  is  usually  priced  at  a  level  much 
higher  than  the  identical  article  sold  under  its  standard  chemical 
nomeuclature.     (See  pt.  I,  ch.  Ill,  table  4,  supra,  p.  77.) 

(3)  There  is  finally  the  proprietary  drug,  the  formula  for  which  is 
not  found  in  the  pharmacopoeia  and  which  is,  in  a  sense,  a  unique 
product  not  precisely  duplicated  by  any  other  manufacturer.  Such  a 
product  is  known  only  by  its  proprietary  name  (e.  g.,  Ex-Lax,  Alka 
Seltzer,  Carter's  Liver  Pills)  and  cannot  be  compared  exactly  with 
any  other  article  serving  a  similar  purpose. 


CHAPTER  II 
RETAIL  MARKETS 

RETAIL    PHICE    TRBNI>S,    1929-1939 

It  is  in  the  light  of  the  general  characteristics  which  imve  been 
described  in  the  last  chapter  that  retail  price  behavior  in  the  drug 
trade  must  be  appraised.  The  information  for  this  analysis  comes 
from  the  Retail  Price  Division  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics 
which  has  collected  retail  price  data  for  certain  drugSj  toiletries,  and 
sundries  for  many  years.  For  most  of  the  individual  items  discussed 
here  quotations  have  been  obtained  in  recent  years  from  over  130 
stores  located  in  32  cities  scattered  throughout  the  United  States;  5 
quotations  are  obtained  from  New  York  City  and  Chicago  and  4 
from  each  of  the  remaining  cities.  This  coverage  is  clearly  too  small 
to  be  adequately  representative  of  the  approxmiately  57,000  ^  drug 
stores  in  the  United  States.  This  is  particularly  true  with  regard  to 
independent  stores,  since  convenience  of  collection  made  it  desirable 
to  concentrate  on  outlets  of  at  least  moderate  size,  located  centrally 
or  near  good  transportation  facilities,  largely  to  the  exclusion  of  very 
small  stores  and  of  stores  located  in  rural  or  outlying  areas.  The 
group  of  reporting  chain  stores  is  probably  more  representative,  espec- 
ially because  quotations  from  one  outlet  of  a  chain  frequently  hold 
true  for  other  outlets  of  the  same  chain  in  the  same  general  locality. 
To  some  extent,  moreover,  the  wide  geographic  distribution  compen- 
sates for  the  small  number  of  reporting  stores  in  any  given  city. 

In  any  analysis  of  price  trends  for  products  handled  by  the  drug 
trade,  it  is  essential  to  consider  individual  brands  separately  and  this 
has  further  limited  the  number  of  quotations  available  for  each  prod- 
uct since  not  all  stores  report  prices  for  the  same  brand.  For  all 
practical  purposes  each  distinct  brand  constitutes  a  distinct  com- 
modity. The  prices  of,  say,  a  nationally  advertised  and  a  nonadver- 
tised  brand  of  toothpaste  display  no  closer  relationship  to  each 
other  than  does  the  price  of  toothpaste  to  that  of  razor  blades. 

The  data  assembled  from  these  records  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor 
Statistics  are  given  in  tables  1  to  6,  which  show  the  recent  trend  of 
retail  prices  for  six  widely  used  drugs,  toiletries,  or  sundries.  Data 
are  available  as  far  back  as  1929  for  the  product  shown  in  table  1 ;  for 
all  the  others  comparable  information  only  extends  to  1935  and  1936. 
Each  of  these  products  is  chosen  to  illustrate  a  somewhat  different 
type  of  market  situation.  In  general,  the  data  presented  in  the  tables 
indicate  that,  in  the  absence  of  resale  price  maintenance,  there  is 
usually  wide  variation  between  the  prices  charged  by  different  retailers 
for  any  one  article.  Some  stores  will  sell  at  the  full  list  price,  others 
at  moderate  reductions  below  list,  others  cut  prices  very  deeply.^ 
However,  where  minimum  prices  have  been  established  by  contract 

'  U.  8.  Department  of  Commerce,  Census  of  Business:  1935,  Retail  Distribution,  vol.  I,  pp.  1-08. 
'  In  the  case  of  most  widely  advertised  items,  trade  custom  sanctioned  reductions  not  exceeding  10  or  20 
percent  below  the  list  price,  but  resented  any  "deep  cut"  prices  below  this  level. 

355 


356 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


the  price  range  is  much  narrower  and,  where  minimum  prices  have 
been  estabUshed  at  the  full  Ust  price  of  the  article,  prices  for  aU  stores 
will  tend  to  be  uniform.  The  tables  suggest,  too,  that  price  cutting 
at  retail  over  a  period  of  time  may  cause  progressive  readjustments 
in  the  wholesale  prices  charged  by  the  manufacturer  but  that  the 
establishment  of  minimum  prices  may  make  such  readjustments 
unnecessary. 


Table  L- 


-Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  analgesic  tablets,  June  1929-June 
1939 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 

TO 

55 

to 

t^ 

rm 

O! 

05 

Price 

h 

CO 

o> 

05 

35 

p 

a 

B 

i 

3 

X3 

a 

Q 

a 

> 

•g 

2 
a 

o 
O 

3 

s 

>> 
5 

J2 

0 
S 

P 

a 
g 

o 

p 

i 

>-> 

X3 

a 
p 

JS 

05 

Q 

$0.08 

2 

1 

$0.10 

1 
1 

1 

7 

5 

9 

5 

4 

1 

3 

1 

1 

$0  11 

$0.12 

3 
1 

1 

1 

32 

3 
3 

3 
2 

3 
2 
1 
1 

58 
1 

2 
2 

1 

4 
2 
1 

21 

1 
6 

28 

24 

29 

32 

37 

35 

37 

38 

42 
1 
6 

1 
30 

40 

1 

5 

2 

31 

46 
1 
6 
1 

25 

50 

$0,125 

$0.13       

5 

3 

3 

1 
39 

2 

1 

39 

3 

1 
37 

3 

1 
37 

5 

1 
35 

5 

1 
34 

fi 

$0.14 

3 
45 

"64" 

? 

$0.15 

60 

62 

44 

41 

43 

21 

$0  17 

$0.18 

9 

5 

25 

?, 

4 
4 
17 

3 
3 
14 

3 
3 
7 

2 
2 
8 

2 

1 
6 

$0  19 

$0  20 

$0.25 

Total 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

79 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

Analgesic  tabids. — Table  1  is  for  l,  widely  used  nationally  advertised 
brand  of  analgesic  tablets.  It  Ulustratds  the  tendency  for  the  price 
of  products  of  this  kind  to  break  away  from  the  nominal  list  price  in 
the  absence  of  legal  controls,  as  well  as  the  change  in  the  situation 
which  occurs  after  such  controls  are  imposed,  bringing  more  uniform 
and  rigid  prices  to  consumers. 

Between  June  1929  and  May  1934,  the  nominal  list  price  of  this 
product  was  20  cents.  During  the  latter  month,  both  the  wholesale 
price  and  the  list  price  were  reduced,  the  latter  dropping  to  15  cents. 
This  was  reflected  in  the  sharp  change  in  the  prevaUing  prices  charged 
between  June  and  November  1934.  (Retail  prices  in  June  1934  did 
not  yet  show  the  full  effect  of  the  change  in  the  wholesale  level  during 
May.)  Between  June  1929  and  June  1934  there  was  a  gradual  break- 
down of  the  retail  price  structure,  though  wholesale  prices  were  not 
reduced.  At  the  beginning  of  this  period  more  than  one-third  of  the 
reported  quotations  were  at  full  list  price  and  two  were  actually  above 
list.  The  number  of  quotations  at  20  cents  declined  steadily  and  by 
the  time  the  wholesale  price  was  reduced,  only  six  of  the  quotations 
remained  at  full  list.  In  the  meantime,  15  cents,  which  had  been  the 
typical  cut  price  in  1929,  became  more  and  more  the  accepted  price, 
accounting  for  over  three-fourths  of  the  quotations  during  1933  and 
the  first  half  of  1934.  In  addition  there  was  a  considerable  and  in- 
creasing number  of  outlets  quoting  prices  substantially  below  the 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  357 

15-cent  level — 12  cents  and  two  for  25  cents.  During  the  latter  part 
of  this  period,  one  or  two  quotations  were  recorded  as  low  as  10  cents, 
or  50  percent  below  the  nominal  list.  To  some  extent,  therefore,  the 
reduction  of  wholesale  prices  during  May  1934  merely  represented  a 
readjustment  to  a  change  which  had  already  taken  place  in  the  retail 
market.  The  sequence  of  events  is  of  interest  because  a  decline  in  the 
retail  market  preceded  that  in  the  wholesale  market,  and  may  have 
been  a  factor  in  inducing  the  manufacturer  to  announce  his  reduction. 

The  drop  in  wholesale  prices  was  not  appreciably  reflected  in  retail 
quotations  until  November  1934.  The  new  list  price,  15  cents,  now 
became  the  maximum  price,  and  12  cents,  which  had  earlier  been 
quoted  by  only  a  few  outlets,  became  the  common  "reduced"  price. 
Outlets  which  wanted  to  cut  deeply  below  the  prevailing  market  and 
which  had  earlier  been  charging  12  cents  or  two  for  25  cents  now  came 
down  to  10  cents. 

Between  November  1934  and  January  1936  there  were  indications 
that  the  sequence  of  changes  which  had  occurred  between  1929  and 

1934  might  be  repeated.  The  number  of  quotations  at  full  list  de- 
clined, those  at  the  usual  cut  price  of  12  cents  increased  rapidly,  and 
an  appreciable  number  of  stores  charged  a  "deep  cut"  price  of  10 
cents  or  even  8  cents. 

In  the  absence  of  resale  price  maintenance,  it  is  entirely  possible 
that  this  would  have  led  eventually  to  a  new  reduction  at  wholesale 
prices  and  a  further  drop  at  retail.  From  the  point  of  view  of  the 
manufacturer  such  a  change  might  well  have  been  feasible  because  the 
cost  of  the  ingredients  of  this  pharmaceutical,  as  in  the  case  of  most 
widely  advertised  proprietary  medicines,  is  quite  small  in  relation  to 
its  wholesale  price. 

However,  resale  price  maintenance  was  held  constitutional  by  the 
United  States  Supreme  Court  during  December  1936  and  minimum 
price  contracts  for  this  product  are  now  in  effect  in  44  States.  As  a 
result,  sales  below  the  12-cent  minimum  became  less  frequent  after 
1936  and  have  now  been  completely  discontinued  by  retailers  report- 
ing to  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics,  including  even  those  located  in 
areas  in  which  price  maintenance  legislation  is  not  in  effect.  The 
most  common  price  at  the  present  time  is  the  minimum  price  and  the 
number  of  quotations  at  the  full  list  price  has  continued  to  decline. 
In  this  last  respect,  however,  it  is  questionable  whether  the  establish- 
ment of  the  legal  minimum  at  12  cents  did  more  than  confirm  a  trend 
which  had  been  evident  since  1934.  The  evidence  available  is  insuflfi- 
cient  to  indicate  whether  the  establishment  of  a  legal  minimum  either 
retarded  or  accelerated  this  trend;  it  did,  however,  set  a  limit  beyond 
which  it  cannot  go,  and  possibly  obviated  the  need  for  a  periodic 
readjustment  of  the  wholesale  level  to  compensate  for  the  progressive 
break-down  of  the  retail  price  structure, 

A  drug  sundry. — Table  2  is  for  a  nationally  advertised  brand  of  drug 
sundry  and  shows  how  the  establishment  of  contractual  minimum 
prices  tends  to  narrow  the  range  of  price  variability.     During  August 

1935  the  manufacturer  "suggested"  the  retail  price  of  18  cents.  On 
June  29,  1936,  this  was  increased  to  19  cents.  Since  May  1937,  min- 
imum prices  have  been  established  by  contract  at  20  cents,  or  two 
for  39  cents.  Between  1935  and  1939,  wholesale  prices  were  increased 
in  about  the  same  proportion. 


358 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


During  1935  and  1936,  while  the  prices  su^ested  by  the  manufac- 
turer (18  cents  and  later  19  cents)  were  the  quotations  most  com- 
monly reported,  there  was  considerable  variation  both  above  and 
below  this  suggested  level.  After  price  maintenance  became  effec- 
tive, the  number  of  stores  quoting  the  minimum  increased  rapidly. 
As  of  March  1939,  102  of  107  stores  reported  prices  of  either  20  cents 
or  two  for  39  cents,^  three  stores  reported  slightly  higher  prices,  and 
two,  both  located  in  non-"fair-trade"  States,  charged  slightly  low^er 
prices. 

Of  course  this  does  not  imply  that  the  establishment  of  minimum 
resale  prices  necessarily  eliminates  all  the  influences  making  for  peri- 
odic downward  readjustment  of  the  wholesale  price  structure,  but 
merely  that  it  impairs  one  of  the  processes  leading  to  such  readjust- 
ment. Where  similar  rival  products  offer  effective  price  competition, 
manufacturers  must  still  adjust  their  price  policies  in  order  to  avoid 
loss  of  volume.  However,  there  are  many  widely  advertised  drugs 
and  toiletries  which  are  not  subject  to  any  effective  price  competition 
from  rival  merchandise  and  for  these  the  ability  of  the  manufacturer 
to  stabilize  the  retail  price  structure  may  considerably  increase  his 
degree  of  control  over  the  wholesale  price  structure  also. 

A  shaving  article. — Table  3  represents  a  very  different  situation. 
The  product  in  this  case  is  a  nationally  advertised  shaving  article. 
The  full  list  price  is  25  cents  and  the  minimum  price  has  been  estab- 
lished by  contract  at  this  same  level  in  aU  "fair-trade"  States  except 
New  York,  where  the  minimum  is  24  cents.  Before  resale  price  main- 
tenance became  effective,  there  was  a  substantial  number  of  quota- 
tions well  below  list,  most  commonly  at  19  cents.  These  reduced 
prices  have  all  had  to  be  discontinued  and  all  quotations  are  now  at 
the  legal  minimum  of  25  cents,  with  the  exception  of  a  few  stores,  all 
located  in  New  York  State,  where  the  minimum  is  1  cent  lower. 
This  uniformity,  which  required  substantial  price  advances  by  a  num- 
ber of  stores,  seems  inevitable  when  the  minimum  price  and  the  full 
list  price  coincide. 


Table  2.- 


-Retail  prices  of  nationally  advertised  drug  sundry,  March  19S5-March 
19S9 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 

Price 

March 
1936 

July 
1935 

October 
1935 

Janu- 
ary 
1936 

July 
1936 

Decem- 
ber 
1936 

June 
1937 

Decem- 
ber 
1937 

June 
1938 

Decem- 
ber 
1938 

March 
1939 

$0.14 

6 

5 
2 

1 

6 

1 

47 

1 

1 

1 

$0.16 

$0.16 

2 
44 

$0.17 

1 

2 

62 

2 

7 
66 

2 

2 

31 

6 

2 
2 
7 
6 

2/$0.35 

1 
2 

1 
1 

$0.18 

2/$0.37 

1 

3/$0.56 

1 
25 

7 
64 

6 

f 
1 

i 

2 

6 

91 

2 

1 
1 
1 

1 
1 

8 

93 

1 

$0.19 

2/$0.39 

28 

23 

19 

20 

44 

71 

95 

$0.20 

$0.21 

$0.23 

12 
6 
2 

16 
3 
2 

18 

1 
2 

18 

1 
1 

17 
2 
3 

15 
2 
2 

94 

$0.24 

1 

1 

$0.25 

2 

1 

1 

1 

Total. 

107 

107 

107 

107 

107 

107 

107 

1       107 

107 

107 

107 

Source:  Bureau  pf  Labor  Statistics. 


'The  fact  that  a  store  reported  20  cents  as  Its  price  did  not  mean  that  It  would  not  sell  two  for 39 cents, 
t)ut  merely  that  most  of  Its  sales  were  in  single  units. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


359 


Table  3. — Retail  pricesof  a  nationally  advertised  shaving  article,  March  1935- March 

1939 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 

Price 

March 
1935 

July 
1935 

October 
1935 

Janu- 
ary 
1936 

July 
1936 

Decem- 
ber 
1936 

June 
1937 

Decem- 
ber 
1937 

June 
1938 

Decem- 
ber 
1938 

March 
1939 

$0.14 

1 

$0.16 

2 

1 

3 
1 

2 

1 

1 

' i" 

10 

1 

1 
1 

1 

$0.17.. 

$0.18 

.?0.19 

9 

10 

11 

4 

2 
6 

1 

2 
2 
2 
2 
102 

i 

1 

$0.21 

$0.23 

i 

2 

2 

$0.24 

5 
103 

5 
104 

4 
105 

4 

$0.25 

97 

94 

94 

96 

103 

101 

106 

Total- 

110 

110 

110 

110 

110 

110 

110 

110 

110 

110 

110 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 
Table  A.-r-Retail  prices  of  a  nationally  advertised  dentifrice,  March  1936-March  1939 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 

Price 

March 
1935 

July 
1935 

October 
1935 

Janu- 
ary 
1936 

July 
1936 

Decem- 
ber 
1936 

June 
1937 

Decem- 
ber 
1937 

June 
1938 

Decem- 
ber 
1938 

March 
1939 

$0.24...     .. 

1 
1 

1 

2 
1 

1 

1 

$0.27 

$0.28 

$0.29.  . 

1 

$0.30... 

1 
10 

1 
9 

$0.31 

13 

2 
3 
11 

3 

10 
8 

1 

1 
17 
6 

i 

15 
7 

1 

$0.33 

18 
5 
1 
1 
1 

24 
2 
1 
1 

25 

1 
1 
1 

25 

$0.34.. 

$0.35 

3 

3 

1 

8 

1 
1 

$0.36 

1 

1 

$0.37 

1 
2 
3 

1 

$0.38...     . 

5 
6 

1 

7 
2 

1 

1 
4 

1 

6 
4 

1 

$0.39 

2 

1 

3 

2 

$0.41 



Total- 

28 

28 

28 

28 

28 

28 

28 

28 

28 

23 

28 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

Table  5. — Retail  prices  of  a  nationally  advertised  liquid  laxative,  March  1935-March 

1989 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 

Price 

March 
1935 

July 
1935 

October 
1935 

Janu- 
ary 
1936 

July 
1936 

Decem- 
ber 
1936 

June 
1937 

Decem- 
ber 
1937 

June 
1938 

Decem- 
ber 
1938 

March 
1939 

$0  27 

1 

1 
5 
1 
2 
2 
1 
7 

$0.28 

1 
6 

1. 
7 

1 
1 

1 
1 
1 

1 
3 

i' 

$0.29 

$0.30... 

4 
1 
1 
1 
2 
12 

2 
1 

2 

1 

2 
1 

5 

1 

3 

1 

$0  31 

1 

$0.32 

$0.33-.-     .. 

3 

15 

3 

15 

3 

15 

2 

13 

2 
12 

1 

1 

2 

23 

2 

11 
1 
1 
2 

23 

2 

$0.34 

$0  35 

9 
1 
3 

1 
21 

1 
1 
1 
1 
1 
3 

9 
1 
3 
1 
21 
._ 

2 

1 
2 

12 
2 

$0.36. 

$0.37. 

$0.39 

$0.40 

$0.43....... 

$0.44 

$0.45 

$0.48 

$0.50. 

1 
1 
22 
1 
1 
1 
1 
1 
2 

1 
2 
21 
1 
1 

"i" 

1 

2 

1 

2 

21 

1 
2 
19 
1 
2 
1 
1 
1 
2 

1 
2 
20 
1 
1 
1 

2 
3 
21 
1 
1 
1 

1 

2 

24 

1 

1 

1 
1 
2 

1 

1 
3 

1 
3 

1 
3 

1 
2 

Total. - 

51 

51 

51 

51 

51 

51 

51 

51 

51             51 

61 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 
247149— 41— No.  1 25 


360 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


A  dentifrice. — Table  4  shows  price  changes  since  1935  for  a  nation- 
ally advertised  dentifrice.  The  minimum  price  fixed  by  contract  is 
at  present  33  cents;  the  full  list  price  is  40  cents.  Prior  to  the 
issuance  of  price-maintenance  contracts,  there  was  a  substantial 
degree  of  price  variation,  with  31  cents  being  the  most  common  price 
and  a  considerable  number  of  outlets  charging  both  more  and  less 
than  this  figure.  Since  1936  there  has  been  a  steady  concentration 
of  quotations  at  the  minimum  level,  and  at  the  present  time  only 
three  stores  are  reporting  prices  above  the  minimum. 

A  nationally  advertised  liquid  laxative. — Table  5  is  for  a  nationally 
advertised  liquid  laxative  which  is  sold  under  the  provision  of  the  fair- 
trade  laws  in  only  one  State — California — where  the  minimum  ha& 
been  established  at  39  cents.     The  full  list  price  is  50  cents. 

The  difference  in  the  distribution  of  price  quotations  for  this  prod- 
uct and  for  the  four  price-maintained  articles  previously  described  is 
striking;  23  of  the  51  quotations  are  below  the  39-cent  level  which 
has  been  established  as  a  minimum  price  in  California;  only  4  were 
at  or  near  the  full  list  price.  The  California  minimum  of  39  cents, 
however,  is  also  the  modal  or  most  commonly  quoted  price.  The 
most  frequent  deep-cut  price  is  34  cents,  which  is  approximately  31 
percent  below  list.  The  distribution  of  prices  as  of  March  1939  wa& 
not  markedly  different  from  that  for  March  1935.  It  is  evident  that 
were  this  product  placed  under  price  maintenance  nationally,  with 
the  minimum  the  same  as  that  now  in  force  in  California,  substantial 
price  increases  would  be  necessary. 

A  standard,  unhranded,  liquid  laxative. — The  quotations  in  table  6 
are  for  a  standard  liquid  laxative  (unrelated  to  that  shown  in  table 
5),  which  is  not  sold  under  a  brand  name  but  bottled  directly  by  the 
retail  druggist.  There  is,  of  course,  no  minimum  nor  list  price  for 
this  item.  The  same  laxative  is  sold  frequently  under  a  manufac- 
turer's label  and  a  comparison  between  the  prices  of  the  branded 
and  the  unbranded  product  will  be  presented  subsequently.  (See 
table  25,  p.  374.) 


Table  6.— 

-Retail  prices  of  a  standard  liq 

Mid  laxative,  July  19S6-March  1939 

Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 

Price 

July 
1936 

December 
1936 

June 
1937 

December 
1937 

June 
1938 

December 
1938 

March 
1939 

$0.15 

8 
3 
5 
7 

6 
3 
7 
8 

6 
3 
7 
8 

6 
3 
6 

10 
1 
3 
1 

50 
3 
1 

7 
3 
4 
11 

1 
2 

7 
3 
4 
11 
1 
2 

7 

$0.17 

3 

$0.19 

4 

$0.20 

11 

$0.21 

1 

$0.23 

6 

6 

6 

3. 

$0.24 

$0.2fi 

51 
I 

50 
3 
2 

49- 
4 
2 

52 
3 
1 

63 
2 

1 

53- 

$0.30 

$0.36 

Total 

84 

84 

84 

84 

84 

84 

84 

^oroe:  Bureau  ol  Labor  Statistics. 

This  table  illustrates  the  effect  of  custom  and  common  practice  in 
bringing  about  uniform  quotation  where -a  minimum  is  not  set. 
Fifty-three  of  a  total  of  84  outlets  all  charge  25  cents  for  a  4-ounce 
bottle.     Moreover,  prices  for  this  nonadvertised  item  are  predomi- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         3gl 

nantly  quoted  in  even  figures  (25  cents,  20  cents,  15  cents),  in  con- 
trast with  the  odd  figures  (12  cents,  39  cents,  two  for  39  cents), 
which  have  been  estabUshed  as  fair-trade  minima  for  the  products 
previously  discussed  and  which  were  favored  even  before  price-main- 
tenance contracts  had  been  issued.  There  has  been  a  slight  tendency 
toward  lower  prices  since  1936;  the  number  of  quotations  above  25 
cents  has  decreased  while  the  number  of  stores  reporting  20  cents  has 
increased. 

PRICE    TRENDS CHAINS    COMPARED    WITH    INDEPENDENTS 

The  -foregoing  analysis  indicates  the  price  trends  for  these  drugs 
and  sundries  in  aU  stores  reporting  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics 
regardless  of  whether  they  were  independently  owned  or  were  members 
of  chain  organizations,  in  order  to  indicate  what  kind  of  general  price 
situation  the  consumer  faces.  Prices  quoted  by  chain  stores  and  by 
independents  for  the  same  products  are  now  shown  separately,  in 
tables  7  to  12.  Certain  differences  in  price  behavior  between  these 
two  types  of  outlet  are  apparent  although  the  general  pattern  is  much 
the  same. 

On  the  basis  of  this  very  limited  group  of  commodities,  it  appears 
that  prices  charged  by  chain  drug  stores  for  nationally  advertised 
items  are  on  the  average  somewhat  lower  than  those  charged  by 
independent  drug  stores,  even  when  minimum  prices  are  in  effect. 
However,  where  the  minimum  price  is  identical  with  the  list  price, 
there  is  no  room  for  any  difference  in  pricing  practice  and  all  outlets 
are  likely  to  quote  the  same  figure. 

On  the  otJier  hand,  there  are  many  independent  drug  stores  which 
charge  prices  as  low  as  those  charged  by  any  chain  store  and  the 
price  ranges  clearly  overlap.  It  can  only  be  said,  therefore,  that 
a  larger  proportion  of  chain  stores  than  of  independents  tend  to 
charge  low  prices  for  nationally  advertised  merchandise  and  that, 
in  the  case  of  price-maintained  products,  where  the  minimum  price 
has  been  established  below  the  list  price,  a  larger  proportion  of 
independents  than  of  chains  will  be  foimd  charging  the  full  list  price. 
However,  for  the  one  standard  nonadvertised  product  for  which  data 
were  available,  there  was  no  significant  difference  between  prices 
quoted  by  chain  stores  and  those  quoted  by  independents. 

In  the  case  of  the  nationally  advertised  analgesic  tablets  shown  in 
table  7,  for  example,  20  independent  stores  were  charging  the  full  list 
price  of  20  cents  in  1929  and  the  same  number  were  charging  the 
regular  cut  price  of  15  cents.  Only  one  independent  quoted  less  than 
15  cents.  During  the  same  period  5  chain  stores  reported  a  price 
of  20  cents,  12  reported  15  cents  and  5  charged  12  cents  or  13  cents. 
By  June  1934,  7  independents  but  only  2  chain  stores  continued  quoting 
prices  exceeding  15  cents;  two  independents  and  6  chain  stores  were 
charging  less  than  15  cents.  Subsequent  to  the  wholesale  price  reduc- 
tion which  took  place  during  1934,  the  chain  stores  again  took  the 
lead  in  reducing  prices.  From  November  1934  on,  12  cents  was  the 
price  most  commonly  charged  by  chain  stores  while,  with  the  excep- 
tion of  the  last  period  shown — June  1939 — 15  cents  was  the  price  most 
frequently  reported  by  independents.  As  of  June  1939,  27  of  a  total 
of  30  chain  stores  were  charging  the  fair-trade  minimum,  while  more 
than  half  of  the  independents  were  quoting  more  than  this  minimum. 


362 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table   7. — Retail  prices  of  a  nationally  advertised  analgesic  tablet,   June   1929- 

June  1939 


NUMBER 

OF  INDEPENDENT  STORES  SELLING  ST  DESIGNATED  PRICES 

Retail  price 

§ 

3 

1-5 

i 

d 

M 
0 

3 
1-5 

0 

5 

> 

s 
i 

1 

3 

1 

0 
0 

0 
a 

0 
2 

3 

t-s 

0 

i 

a 
5 

1 
0 

§ 

3 

00 
2 

0 

1 

a 

3 

$0.08 

1 

1 
11 

1 

1 

12 

$0.10 

2 
8 
1 
3 

1 
11 

4 

7 

1 

13 

1 

14 

1 
13 

1 

13 

$0.12 

1 

1 

1 
1 

1 

1 

1 
1 

1 
1 

16 

1 

4 

1 

27 

14 
1 
4 
2 

28 

19 
1 

5 

1 

23 

?3 

$0.12>i 

$0.13 

2 

2 

2 

1 

33 

1 

1 

33 

2 

1 

32 

2 

1 

31 

3 

1 

31 

4 

1 

30 

5 

$0.14 

1 

20 

2 
28 

1 

$0.15 

33 

37 
1 
3 

1 
5 

38 

40 

35 

35 

36 

?n 

$0.17 

$0.18 

6 

1 

20 

1 

I9" 

3 

3 

2 
1 
6 

2 

$0.19 .• 

.$0  20 

14 

11 

5 

$0  25 

Total 

"49" 

~49" 

"49" 

49 

"49" 

"49" 

I9" 

"49" 

l9~ 

49 

IT 

49 

49 

"49" 

Ig" 

49 

"49" 

~49 

NUMBER  OF  CHAIN  STORES  SELLING  AT  DESIGNATED  PRICES 


$0  08 

1 
4 

..   - 

$0.10 

■ 

1 

5 

4 

5 

3 

2 

$0.11  .          .  .. 

$0.12 

3 

1 
1 

2 
2 

2 

1 

2 

1 

1 

1 

21 

3 
1 
1 

13 

17 

17 

18 

20 

24 

21 

24 

25 

26 

26 

27 

?7 

$0.12Vi 

.$0.13 

3 

3 

1 

1 

1 

1 

1 

2 

1 

1 

1 

1 

1 

$0  14 

1 

17 
1 
4 
3 

21' 

1 

$0.15 

12 
3 

4 
5 

1 

30 

22 

22 

9 

6 

7 

6 

6 

5 

6 

4 

4 

3 

3 

2 

1 

$0.13 

$0  19 

3 
3 

2 
2 

1 
2 

1 
1 

$0.20 

$0.25 

Total 

30 

30 

~W 

IT 

30 

'W 

30 

30 

30 

"so" 

"so" 

30 

~30~ 

lo~ 

"so" 

'W 

'W 

30 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

Table  8. — Retail  prices  of  a  nationally  advertised  drug  sundry — March  1935  to 

March  1939 

NUMBER  OF  INDEPENDENT  STORES  REPORTING  SPECIFIED  PRICES 


Retail 
Price 

March 
1935 

July 
1935 

Octo- 
ber 1935 

Janu- 
ary 1936 

July 
1936 

Decem- 
ber 1936 

June 
1937 

Decem- 
ber 1937 

June 
1938 

Decem- 
ber 1938 

March. 
1939 

$0.14 

1 

1 

14 

21 

12 

2 

2 

2 
1 

15 
19 
12 
3 
2 

$0.17 

26" 
17 
14 

1 
2 

20 
17 
14 

2 
14 
23 
13 
1 
2 

1 
5 
34 
11 
2 
2 

$0.18 

$0.19 

$0.20. 

$0.21 

$0.23 

2 
16 
32 

3 

.. 

1 

1 
2 

47 
2 
1 
1 
1 

50 

1 

1 

51 

1 

1 
1 
51 

1 

$0.24 

1 

1 

$0.25 

2 

1 

1 

Total- 

55 

55 

55 

55  1          55 

55 

55 

55 

55 

55 

55 

NUMBER  OF  CHAIN  STORES  REPORTING  SPECIFIED  PRICES 


$0.14 

4 

3 
2 
1 
5 

1 
32 

1 

1 

1 

$0.15 

$0.16 

$0.17 

5 

2 
30 

1 

2 
42 

1 

7 
36 

2 

17 

5 

1 

2 

2 

6 

2/$0.35    or 
$0.17^4... 

1 

1 

$0.18 

2/$0.37    or 
$0.18h... 

3/$0.56    or 
$0.28 

1 
9 

7 

32 

2 

1 

1 

$0.19 

7 

4 

2 

3 

21 

37 

2/$0  39    or 
$0.19^... 

6 
■     44 

8 
43 

8 
44 

s 

$0.20 

4 

4 

4 

4 

1 
1 

4 

43 
1 

$0.21 

4 

$0.23 

Total.. 

52 

52 

52 

52 

62 

52  1          52 

52 

52 

52 

52 

Source:  I 

3ureau  0 

Labor  S 

tatistlcs. 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


363 


Table  9. — Retail  prices  of  a  nationally  advertised  shaving  article,  March-  19S5- 

March  t939 

NUMBER  OF  INDEPENDENT  STORES  SELLING  AT  DESIGNATED  PRICES 


Retail 
Price 

March 
1935 

July 
1935 

Octo- 
ber 1935 

Janu- 
ary 1936 

July 
1936 

Decem- 
ber 1936 

June 
1937 

Decem- 
ber 1937 

June 
1938 

Decem- 
ber 1938 

March 
1939 

$0.14 

1 

$0.16 

1 
3 

1 
3 

1 
3 

1 
3 

1 
1 

1 

$0.19 

1 

1 

1 

$0.21    . 

$0.23 

1 

2 

2 

1 

1 

2 

$0.24 

1 

57 

1 

56 

$0.25. 

53 

52 

52 

52 

56 

56 

65 

57 

58 

Total.. 

58 

58 

68 

68 

58 

68 

58 

58 

68 

68 

58 

NUMBER  OF  CHAIN  STORES  SELLING  AT  DESIGNATED  PRICES 


$0.14 

$0.16 

1 
1 

2 
1 

i 

1 

i' 

7 

1 
1 

$0  17 

$0.18 

$0.19 

$0.21 

6 

7 

8 

3 

1 
6 

1 
2 

1 
1 

$0  23 

$0.24 

2 

47 

4 

46 

4 
48 

4 
48 

4 

$0.25 

44 

42 

42 

44 

47 

45 

48 

Total.. 

52 

52 

62 

62 

52 

52 

52 

52 

52 

62 

52 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


Table  10. — Retail  prices  of  a  nationally  advertised  dentifrice,  March  1935-March  1939 

NUMBER  OF  INDEPENDENT  STORES  REPORTING  SPECIFIED  PRICES 


Retail 
Price 

March 
1935 

July 
1935 

Octo- 
ber 1935 

Janu- 
ary 1936 

July 
1936 

Decem- 
ber 1936 

June 
1937 

Decem- 
ber 1937 

June     Decem- 
1938     ber  1938 

March 
1939 

$0  30 

1- 

$0.31 

$0.33 

4 

4 

3 

2 

1 
2 

1 

1 
3 
2 

1 
4 
2 

5 
2 

6              6 

6 

$0.34       .  . 

1 

1 

1 

1 

$0  35 

1 

1 

1 

1 

1 

$0  36 

1 

1 

$0.38 

$0.39 

$0.41 

1 
3 

1 

2 

2 

1 

1 
3 
1 

2 
3 
1 

2 
3 

2 
1 

2 

1 

I  .           .  1 

Total.. 

9 

9              9  !           9 

1 

9 

9 

9  j           9 

9 

9 

9 

NUMBER  OF  CHAIN  STORES  REPORTING  SPECIFIED  PRICES 


$0  24 

1 
1 
1 

2 

1 

$0  27 

1 

1 

$0  28 

$0  29 

1 

$0.30 

i 

6 

$0.31 

$0.33.. 

9 

6 

3" 

10 

2 
8 

7 

1 

14 
4 

11 
6 
1 

13 
3 

1 

18 
1 

19 

19 

$0.34. 

$0  35 

3 

3 
1 

8 

$0.36 

$0  37 

1 

1 

1 

1 

$0.38..:.... 
$0.39 

4 
2 

5 

l" 

4 
1 

. 

1 

1 

Total.. 

19 

19 

19 

19 

19 

19 

19 

19  !          19            19 

19 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


364 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  11  — Retail  prices  of  a  nationally  advertiaed  liquid  laxative,  March  19S5- 

March  19S9 

NUMBER  OF  INDEPENDENT  STORES  REPORTING  SPECIFIED  PRICES 


RetaU 
Price 

March 
1935 

July 
1935 

Octo- 
ber 1935 

Janu- 
ary 1936 

July 
1936 

Decem- 
ber 1936 

June 
1937 

Decem- 
ber 1937 

Jime 
1938 

Decem- 
ber 1938 

March 
1939 

$0  27 

$0  28 

$0.29 

$0  30 

3 

3 

1 

2 

1 

2 

3 

2 

1 

1 

1 

1 

1 

$0  31 

$0  32 

$0.33 

1 
2 

1 
4 

I 
6 

1 
6 

1 
6 

1 
5 

1 
4 

1 

1 
3 

1 

1 

$0.34 

$0.35 

$0.36 

$0.37 

$0.39 

$0.40 

$0.43 

$0  44 

2 

16 

3 

1 

1 

1 

15 

i 

4 

1 

1 

17 
1 
1 

1 
16 

1 
1 

1 

17 

1 
1 

1 
15 

1 
2 

1 

16 
1 

1 

1 
17 

1 
1 

18 

18 

19 

1 

1 

$0.45 

$0.48 

$0.50 

3 

2 
1 
2 

1 
1 
2 

1 
1 
2 

1 
1 
1 

1 
1 
2 

1 
1 
2 

1 

1 
3 

1 
3 

i 

3 

1 
2 

Total- 

31 

31 

31 

31 

31 

31 

31 

31 

31 

31 

31 

NUMBER  OF  CHAIN  STORES  REPORTING  SPECIFIED  PRICES 


$0.27 

1 
1 
2 

$0.28  

1 
3 

1 
4 

1 
1 

1 
1 

$0.29 

$0.30 

2 

2 

2 

2 

2 

1 

1 
1 

$0.31 

1 

1 

2 
2 

1 
1 
1 

8 

1 

$0.32 

$0.33    

2 
9 

2 
9 

2 
9 

1 

8 

1 

8 

1 
8 

1 

$0.34 

$0.35 

7 

6 

5 

8 

1 

$0.36 

$0.37 

2 

2 

1 

1 

1 
5 

1 
1 
4 

1 
1 
4 

1 
1 
4 

2 
2 
4 

1 
2 

5 

1 

2 
5 

1 
2 

$0.39 

$0.40 

5 

6 

5 

5 

$0.43 

$0.44 

1 

1 

1 

1 

1 

1 

$0.45 

$0.48  

$0.50 

Total.. 

20 

20 

20 

20 

20 

20 

20 

20 

20 

20 

20 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

A  somewhat  similar  comparison  is  indicated  for  the  other  price 
maintained  products  shown  in  tables  8,  9,  and  10.  Before  the  ad- 
vent of  price  maintenance,  price  cutting  was  more  pronounced  among 
the  chains  than  among  the  independents;  after  minimum  prices  were 
prescribed,  practically  all  chains  adhered  to  these  minima,  while  a 
few  independents  continued  to  quote  prices  above  these  minima.  In 
the  case  of  the  shaving  article  shown  in  table  9,  all  independent 
stores  charged  the  full  list  price  even  in  New  York  where  the  mini- 
mum was  1  cent  lower,  but  all  the  chain  stores  in  New  York  charged 
the  reduced  price.  No  minimum  price  was  fixed  by  contract  for  the 
nationally  advertised  liquid  laxative  shown  in  table  11,  except  in 
California.  As  mentioned  earlier,  the  full  list  price  of  this  product 
is  50  cents  and  the  California  minimum  39  cents.  Four  independents 
but  no  chain  stores  charged  more  than  this  Cahfomia  minimum. 
More  than  half  of  the  independent  stores  quoted  39  cents,  while 
three-fourths  of  the  chains  charged  less  than  39  cents. 

There  is  much  less  difference  evident  in  the  case  of  the  nonadver- 
tised  laxative  shown  in  table  12.  The  price  distribution  is  much  the 
same  for  both  chain  stores  and  independents. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


365 


Table  12. — Retail  prices  of  a  standard  liquid  laxative,  July  19S6-March  19S9 

NUMBER  OF  INDEPENDENT  STORES  REPORTING  SPECIFIED  PRICES 


Retail  price 

July  1936 

December 
1936 

June  1937 

December 
1937 

June  1938 

December 
1938 

March 
1939 

$0.15 

$0.19 

3 

1 
6 
1 

3 

1 
6 

3 
2 
5 
1 

3 
2 
6 
1 

1 

29 

1 

3 
2 
6 

3 
2 
6 

3 
2 

$0.20 

6 

$0.23 

$0.24 

$0.25 

31 

1 

32 

1 

31 
1 

31 
1 

31 
1 

31 

$0.35 

1 

Total. 

43 

43 

43 

43 

43 

43 

43 

NUMBER  OF  CHAIN  STORES  REPORTING  SPECIFIED  PRICES 


$0.15 

5 
3 
4 
1 

3 
3 

6 
2 

3 
3 
5 
3 

3 
3 

4 
4 
1 
2 
21 
3 

4 
3 

2 

5 
1 
2 
21 
3 

4 
3 
2 

5 
1 
2 
22 
2 

4 

$0.17 

3 

$0.19               ... 

2 

$0.20 

5 

$0.21 

1 

$0.23 

4 

20 
3 
1 

5 
18 
3 

1 

4 

18 

4 

1 

3 

$0.25 

22 

$0.30 

1 

$0  35 

Total 

41 

41 

41 

41 

41 

41 

41 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

Retail  prices  as  reported  by  the  Marketing  Laws  Survey. — The  rela- 
tively small  number  of  drug  stores  reporting  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor 
Statistics  limits  the  degree  to  which  the  foregoing  comparisons  can 
be  considered  generally  representative,  particularly  for  independent 
outlets.  Some  light  may  be  thrown  upon  this  question  by  the  re- 
sults of  a  field  study  conducted  by  the  more  comprehensive  Market- 
ing Laws  Survey  of  the  Works  Progress  Administration  in  Columbus, 
Ohio,  during  August  1938.  Although  this  was  confined  to  one  city, 
it  covered  many  more  drug  stores  than  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics 
reporting  list. 

The  results  of  this  survey  show  that  prices  charged  by  independent 
Columbus  drug  stores  for  these  products  were  somewhat  higher  than 
those  of  independent  stores  reporting  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics 
and  that  the  foregoing  analysis,  confined  largely  to  stores  of  at  least 
moderate  size  located  near  convenient  transportation  facilities,  may 
indicate  a  greater  degree  of  price  uniformity  than,  in  fact,  exists. 
The  only  exception  was  the  case  of  the  shaving  article  (table  15), 
where  the  minimum  price  and  the  hst  price  coincided.  This  is  shown 
in  tables  13  to  17  inclusive,  which  compare  the  distribution  of  prices 
as  reported  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  during  Jime  1938  with 
those  obtained  by  the  Marketing  Laws  Survey  in  Columbus  for  the 
first  five  of  the  products  which  have  been  described.  (The  only  item 
omitted  was  the  standard  liquid  laxative  shown  in  tables  6  and  12.) 
It  is  beheved  that  the  group  of  stores  visited  during  the  course  of 
the  Marketing  Laws  Survey  was  adequately  representative  of  all 
types  of  independent  retail  drug  stores  in  Columbus.  However,  the 
number  of  chain  store  quotations  obtained  was  less  adequate. 

In  the  case  of  the  analgesic  tablets  for  example,  (table  13),  74  percent 
of  the  Columbus  stores  charged  the  full  Hst  price  and  only  10  percent 
charged  the  minimum  as  compared  with  55  and  33  percent  respectively 
for  Uie  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  group.     In  the  case  of  the  drug 


366 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


sundry  (table  14),  only  three  of  the  55  independent  stores  reported 
prices  above  the  minimum  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics,  while 
almost  half  of  the  Columbus  stores  charged  more  than  the  minimum; 
the  highest  price  reported  to  the  Bureau  was  25  cents,  while  prices  in 
Columbus  ranged  as  high  as  32  cents.  Almost  half  the  Columbus 
stores  charged  39  cents  for  the  dentifrice  (table  16),  a  price  higher 
than  any  reported  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  for  the  same 
period.  In  the  case  of  the  liquid  laxative  (table  17),  the  same  con- 
trast is  evident;  the  price  most  commonly  reported  was  45  cents,  while 
that  most  frequently  recorded  by  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  was 
39  cents. 

The  same  general  situation  holds  for  a  widely  advertised  proprietary 
cold  remedy  (table  18).  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  data  for  this 
article  were  available  only  for  Jirne  1939.  The  full  list  price  was  35 
cents  and  the  minimum  fair-trade  price  was  27  cents.  Eighty-four 
percent  of  the  chain  outlets  reporting  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics 
quoted  the  minimum  price  with  the  remainder  evenly  divided  below 
and  above  the  minimum.  (The  prices  below  the  minimum  were 
reported  for  States  in  which  there  was  no  price-maintenance  legis- 
lation.) 

Table  13. —  Retail  prices  of  a  nationally  advertised  analgesic  tablet 


Chain  drug  stores 

Independent  drug  stores 

Price 

B.  L.  S. 
data  32 
cities 

W.  P.  A. 

data 

Columbus, 

Ohio 

B.L.  S. 
data  32 
cities 

W.  P.  A. 

data 

Columbus, 

Ohio 

$0.12.. 

26 

4 

16 

5 

2/$0.25      ... 

1 

$0.13 

1 

1 

4 

1 
27 

5 

$0.14 

3 

$0.15 

3 

37 

Total 

30 

5 

49 

60 

Source;  Bureau  o(  Labor  Statistics  (June  1938)  and  Marketing  Law  Survey,  W.  P.  A.  project,  Columbus, 
Ohio  (August  1938). 

Table  14. — Retail  prices  of  a  nationally  advertised  drug  sundry 


Chain  drug  stores 

Independent  drug  stores 

Price 

B.  L.  S. 
data  32 
cities 

W.  P.  A. 

data 

Columbus, 

Ohio 

B.  L.  S. 

data  32 
cities 

W.  P.  A, 

data 

Columbus 

Ohio 

$0.18 .. 

1 

3/$0.5e 

1 

$0.19 " 

1 

X 

2/$0.39 

8 
43 

2 
4 

$0.20 

50 

1 

12 

$0.21 

2 

»r,.23 

4 

$0.24   " 

1 
1 

2 

$0.25 

$0.29 

1 

$0.30 " 

1 

$0.32 " 

1 

Total 

62 

6 

66 

24 

.. — 

Ohlo"(AuSieM)°'  ^^^^  statistics  (June  1938)  and  Marketing  Law  Survey,  W.  P.  A.  project,  Columbus, 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  3^7 

Table  15. — Retail  prices  of  a  nationally  advertised  shaving  article 


Chain  drug  stores 

Independent  drug  stores 

Price 

B.  L.  S. 
data  32 
cities 

W.  P.  A. 

data 

Columbus, 

Ohio 

B.  L.  S. 
data  32 
cities 

W.  P.  A. 

data 

Columbus 

Ohio 

$0.14 

1 

1 

56 

$0.24 

4 

48 

$0.25 

3 

16 

Total              

62 

3 

58 

10 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  (June  1938)  and  Marketing  Law  Survey,  W.  P.  A.  project,  Columbus, 
Ohio  (August  1938). 

Table  16. — Retail  prites  of  a  nationally  advertised  dentifrice 


Chain  drug  stores 

Independent  drug  stores 

Price 

B.  L.  S. 

data,  32 

cities 

W.  P.  A. 

data, 

Columbus, 

Ohio 

B.  L.  S. 

data,  32 

cities 

W.  P.  A. 

data, 

Columbus, 

Ohio 

$0.33                        

18 

1 

2 

6 
1 
1 

1 

7 

$0.34 

$0.35 

1 

$0.36  .. 

1 

$0.39     -              

7 

Total 

19 

2 

9 

16 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  (June  1938)  and  Marketing  Law  Survey,  W.  P.  A.  project,  Columbus, 
Ohio  (August  1938). 

Table  17. — Retail  prices  of  a  nationally  advertised  liquid  laxative 


Chain  drug  stores 

Independent  drug  stores 

Price 

B.  L.  S. 

data,  32 

cities 

W.  P.  A. 

data, 

Columbus, 

Ohio 

B.  L.  S. 

data,  32 

cities 

W.  P.  A. 

data, 

Columbus, 

Ohio 

$0.28 

1 
1 
1 
1 
8 

$0.29                                          .                  .          .              

2 

$0.31 

$0.33 

1 
2 

1 
4 
1 

$0.34 

$0.35     

$0.36 

1 
2 
5 

$0.37 

1 

$0.39 

3 

18 

15 

$0.41 

1 

$0.43 

1 

5 

$0.45                                      .                  .              

20 

$0.47 

4 

$0.48 

1 
3 

$0.50...                  

4 

Total     ..          .                                          

20 

6 

21 

50 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  (June  1938)  and  Marketing  Law  Survey,  W.  P.  A.  project,  Columbus, 
Ohio  (August  1938). 


368 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Table  18. — Retail  prices  of  a  nationally  advertised  cold  remedy 


Price 


$0.24. 
$0.25. 
$0.27. 
$0.28. 
$0.29- 
$0.30. 
$0.31. 
$0.32. 
$0.33. 
$0.35. 


Total. 


Chain  drug  stores 


B.  L.  S. 

data,  32 

cities 


50 


W.  P.  A. 

data, 

Columbus, 

Ohio 


Independent  drug  stores 


B.  L.  S. 

data,  32 

cities 


W.  P.A 

data, 

Columbus, 

Ohio 


55 


Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  (June  1938)  and  Marketing  Law  Survey,  W.  P.  A.  project,  Columbus, 
Ohio  (August  1938). 

Of  the  independent  drug  stores  reporting  to  the  Bureau,  62  percent 
were  at  the  minimum  and  the  remainder  were  above  the  minimum. 
Independent  drug  stores  in  Columbus,  Ohio,  according  to  the  W.  P.  A. 
Survey,  showed  a  tendency  to  charge  somewhat  higher  prices  than  did 
independent  drug  stores  in  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  reporting 
group.  Eighty  percent  quoted  more  than  the  minimum  and  the  price 
most  frequently  charged  was  29  cents  rather  than  27  cents. 

The  small  number  of  quotations  available  for  chain  drug  stores  in 
Columbus  precludes  any  adequate  comparison  with  prices  reported  to 
the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.  To  the  extent  to  which  data  are  avail- 
able, however,  the  distribution  of  prices  does  not  differ  greatly.  More- 
over, since  prices  reported  by  chain  stores  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor 
Statistics  are  often  representative  of  prices  charged  by  all  outlets  of 
the  given  chain  in  each  locality,  it  seems  probable  that  chain-store 
prices  reported  to  the  Bureau  are  fairly  representative  of  general 
practice. 

Apparently,  therefore,  prices  reported  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Sta- 
tistics by  independent  retail  drug  outlets  are  somewhat  lower  than  is 
true  for  independent  drug  stores  generally.  This  is  probably  due  to 
the  fact  that  small  independent  druggists,  and  especially  those  who 
are  not  located  adjacent  to  good  transportation  facilities,  charge  some- 
what higher  prices  for  nationally  advertised  merchandise  than  do  the 
larger  and  more  conveniently  located  stores  from  which  the  Bureau 
compiles  data.  Consequently,  the  difference  between  prices  charged 
by  chain  stores  and  by  independent  drug  stores  generally  is  probably 
somewhat  wider  than  indicated  in  tables  7  to  12  above. 


ADVERTISED  AND  SUBSTITUTE  BRANDS 

The  importance  of  brand  names  and  advertising  in  influencing  the 
prices  of  products  handled  by  the  drug  trade  has  already  been  dis- 
cussed.* In  general,  widely  advertised  products  command  a  substan- 
tial premium  over  less  well-known  or  unbranded  commodities  of  the 
same  general  kind ;  frequently  these  differences  exist  when  the  branded 

«  See  supra,  pp.  80-83. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  3g9 

and  imbranded  commodities  are  identical  except  in  name.  Particu- 
larly wide  price  differentials  are  encountered  between  articles  sold 
under  proprietary  names  and  the  same  articles  bearing  their  standard 
chemical  designations.  Part  I  of  this  volume  includes  a  table  show- 
ing that  for  1 1  standard  drug  products  the  aggregate  cost  per  ounce 
totaled  $28.95  under  the  proprietary  designations  and  only  $4.59  when 
sold  under  their  standard  chemical  names.* 

The  existence  of  these  wide  price  differentials  may  also  have  fur- 
nished retail  druggists  with  an  additional  means  of  persuading  drug 
manufacturers  to  issue  price  maintenance  contracts  guaranteeing  mar- 
gins which  the  retailers  deem  satisfactory.  An  example  of  this  sort  of 
argument  is  described  by  Ewald  T.  Grether  in  a  recent  book  on  the 
subject:" 

Added  to  the  threatened  refusal  to  cooperate  with  manufacturers  who  did  not 
meet  the  demands  of  retailers,  there  was  a  growing  complaint  that  the  pharma- 
cists had  allowed  too  much  manufacturing  to  leave  their  own  establishments. 
John  Culley,  in  a  lengthy  paper  presented  -before  the  Northern  California  Retail 
Druggists'  Association,  November  2,  1935,  appealed  to  pharmacists  to  return  to 
their  former  professional  status.  He  contended  that  retail  druggists  "are  tired  of 
acting  as  a  manufacturer's  distributor  without  pay  and  many  time?  paying  for 
the  privilege."  He  pointed  out  that  as  a  result  of  the  increase  in  trade-marked 
proprietary  products  the  retail  druggist: 

"*  *  *  must  increase  his  investment  without  any  additional  output.  He  is 
obliged  to  keep  in  stock  a  dozen  or  more  varieties  of  trade-marked  brands  of 
proprietary  remedies  having  a  similar  fanciful  coined  name,  all  containing  the 
same  ingredients,  claiming  as  having  the  same  extravagant  medical  virtues  and 
all  outrageously  overpriced,  all  of  which  is  detrimental  to  the  interests  of  the 
pharmacist,  the  physician,  and  to  the  public." 

He  argued  that  if  it  is  ethical  for  manufacturers  to  duplicate  and  imitate  each 
other's  products,  it  is  equally  so  for  the  pharmacist,  and  strongly  advised  him  to 
manufacture  and  introduce  many  of  his  own  products,  thus  giving  him  both  a 
manufacturing  and  retailing  profit.  The  paper  concluded  with  the  following  state- 
ment and  a  number  of  examples  to  illustrate  his  contention. 

"For  your  information  and  convenience  1  will  quote  a  few  cost  prices  on  some 
types  of  preparations  that  can  be  easily  and  quickly  made  by  the  retail  pharmacist 
and  quote  Also  the  cost  price  he  will  have  to  pay  for  a  similar  product  from  the 
large  manufacturer.  It  is  interesting  to  note  that  the  New  Jersey  State  Pharma- 
ceutical Association,  by  means  of  a  standing  professional  committee  recognizes 
the  facts  expressed  in  this  paper  and  have  selected  and  placed  before  their  mem- 
bers many  formulae  for  remedies  that  are  similar  to  well  known  but  drastically 
overpriced  proprietary  trade-marked  articles.  I  have  attached  to  this  paper 
several  formulae  with  working  directions  some  of  which  are  those  recommended 
by  the  N.  F.  Ph.  A.  and  will  be  pleased  to  furnish  them  to  those  interested: 

Elixir  amidopyrine: 

Cost  to  buy 1000  cc  $5.  44 

Cost  to  make do 1.  25 

Elixir  phenobarbital : 

Cost  to  buy  the  proprietary pint__  2.  50 

Cost  to  make  with  theUSP  chemical do .35 

Syrup  potassium  guaiacol  sulphonate: 

Cost  to  buy. . 1000  CC-  3.  00 

Cost  to  make do .  80 

Ephedrine  inhalant: 

Cost  to  buy ._.      do 17.  00 

Cost  to  make do .  80 

Ephedrine  inhalant  compound: 

Cost  to  buy --- -do 17.  00 

Cost  to  make do 1.  35 


•  See  supra,  p.  81. 

•  Price  Control  Under  Fair  Trade  Legislation,  by  Ewald  T.  Grether,  pp.  94-86. 


3yQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Ephedrine  solution  3  percent: 

Cost  to  buy pint--     4.  80 

Cost  to  make do 1.  25 

Solution  ephedrine  and  epinephrine: 

Cost  to  buy-- 1000  cc-  28.  00 

Cost  to  make do 3.  80 

Capsules  ephedrine  sulph.  %  grain  each: 

Cost  to  buy 100..     2.  12 

Cost  to  make do .  34 

Capsules  ephedrine  sulph.  %  grain: 

Cost  to  buy do 3.  50 

Cost  to  make do .  60 

The  following  represent  just  a  few  of  the  USP  and  NF  preparations  that 
can  be  made  much  cheaper  and  easier  than  to  buy  ready-made: 
Brown  mixture: 

Cost  to  buy pint..   $0.  55 

Cost  to  make do .  31 

Rhubarb  and  soda  mixture: 

Cost  to  buy do .  55 

Cost  to  make do .  30 

Elixir  sodium  bromide: 

Cost  to  buy do .  70 

Cost  to  make do .  27 

Elixir  potassium  bromide: 

Cost  to  buy do .  80 

Cost  to  make do .  30 

Elixir  terpin  hydrate: 

Cost  to  buy gallon..     7.  68 

Cost  to  make do 3.  36 

Elixir  terpin  hydrate  and  codeine: 

Cost  to  buy do 8.  50 

Cost  to  make do 5.  36 

Elixir  simple: 

Cost  to  buy do 5.  40 

Cost  to  make.- do 2.  10 

Syrup  hydriodic  acid: 

Cost  to  buy pint..       .  78 

Cost  to  make do .  18 

Syrup  wild  cherry: 

Cost  to  buy  or  make  from  Fluidextr do .  45 

Cost  to  make do .20 

Dobells  solution: 

Cost  to  buy gallon..     1.  25 

Cost  to  make do .25 

Calamine  lotion: 

Cost  to  buy do 1.  50 

Cost  to  make ^..do .  73 

Ointment  white  precipitate: 

Cost  to  buy pound..     1.  26 

Cost  to  make ; do .  60 

Ointment  sulphur: 

Cost  to  buy . do .  67 

Cost  to  make do .  35 

Fehlings  solution: 
Copper  A: 

Cost  to  buy do 1.  00 

Cost  to  make do .  10 

Alkaline  B: 

Cost  to  buy do 1.  00 

Cost  to  make ..^ do .  40 

Benedicts  solution: 

Cost  to  buy pint..       .  60 

Cost  to  make do .  25 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


371 


Price  spreads  between  different  brands  of  articles  sold  under  the 
same  generic  name  (e.  g.,  aspirin,  toothpaste,  codliver  oil)  are  usually 
not  quite  as  wide  as  those  between  drugs  sold  under  their  chemical 
and  their  proprietary  designations,  but  they  may  still  be  very  con- 
siderable. For  example,  a  nationally  advertised  brand  of  aspirin 
sells  at  the  minimum  fair  trade  price  of  59  cents  per  100  tablets;  other 
advertised  brands  of  aspirin  commonly  sell  for  39  cents  per  100  tablets, 
and  private  or  unadvertised  brands  may  be  obtained  regularly  for  19 
cents  and  sometimes  for  as  little  as  8  cents.  One  chain  store  has  two 
private  brands  of  aspirm,  both  presumably  identical  except  for  name; 
yet  one  is  sold  for  39  cents  per  100  tablets  and  the  other  for  19 
cents  per  100.  In  general,  clerks  in  this  chain  do  not  offer  the  19-cent 
article  except  upon  demand  and  even  then  they  have  been  known  to 
sell  it  reluctantly.  The  cheaper  product  is  what  is  usually  known  in 
the  trade  as  a  ''fighting"  brand:  that  is,  it  is  offered  to  meet  the  price 
competition  of  cut-rate  outlets. 

Ordinarily  the  Retail  Price  Division  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics 
collects  prices  only  for  the  brand  most  commonly  sold  in  each  store. 
During  March  and  June  1939,  however,  agents  were  instructed  to 
collect  prices  not  only  upon  the  best  selling  brand — usually  a  nationally 
advertised  product — but  also  for  substitute  or  private  brands  of  the 
same  commodity.  Tables  19  to  26  inclusive  compare  the  prices  quoted 
for  advertised  and  substitute  brands  as  of  June  1939. 


Table  19. — Retail  prices  of  analgesic  tablets,  nationally  advertised  brand  and  substi- 
tute brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores,  June  1939 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 

Retail  price 

Total 

Chain  stores 

Independent  stores 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

$0  02 

1 
2 

1 
1 
1 
4 
103 
1 

1 
2 
1 
1 
1 
3 
50 
1 

$0  03 

$0  05 

$0  07 

$0  08 

$0  09 

1 

$0.10 

53 

$0  12 

77 
1 
6 
3 

27 

55 

22 

1 
5 

1 
25 

2/$0  25 

$0  13 

1 
2 
2 

$0  14 

$0  15 

Total          .  - 

114 

114 

60 

60                    54 

54 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


372 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  20. —  Retail  prices  of  drug  sundry,  nationally  advertised  brand  and  substitute 
brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores,  June  1939 


Retail  price 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 


Total 


Nationally 

advertised 

brand 


Substitute 
brands 


Chain  stores 


Nationally 

advertised 

brand 


Substitute 
brands 


Independent  stores 


Nationally 

advertised 

brand 


Substitute 
brands 


$0.09... 
$0.11... 
$0.12... 
2/$0.25. 
$0.13... 
2/$0.27. 
$0.14--. 
$0.16... 
2/$0.31. 
$0.16... 
$0.17... 
$0.18... 
$0.19... 
2/$0.39. 
$0.20... 


Total. 


82 


82 


52 


30 


30 


Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

Table  21 . — Retail  prices  of  shaving  article,  nationally  advertised  brand  and  substitute 
brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores,  June  1989 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 

Retail  price 

Total 

Chain  stores 

Independent  stores 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

$0.10 

25 
2 
4 
2 

13 
1 

5 
1 
3 
2 
9 

20 

$0.12 

1 

$0.15 

1 

$0.17 

$0.19 

4 

$0.20 

1 

$0.21 

2 

2 

$0.23 

6 

6 

$0.24 

4 
63 

2 
32 

2 
31 

$0.25 

14 
1 

1 

9 

5 

$0.35 

1 

$0.39 

1 

Total 

69 

69 

36 

36 

33 

33 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


I 


I 

\ 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


373 


Table  22. — Retail  prices  of  liquid  laxative  "A,"  nationally  advertised  brand  and 
substitute  brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores,  June  19S9 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 

Price 

Total 

Chain  stores 

Independent  stores 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

$0.11 

1 
2 
2 

1 
1 

1 

$0.19                             

1 

$0.23          

1 

$0  24 

1 

$0.25                                         ■     -. 

4 
3 

X 

1 
3 

3 

$0.27               .                

$0.28 

11 

31 

1 
t 

35 

1 
7 
1 
3 
1 
3 

23 
1 
1 
4 

15 

1 
4 

$0.29 

49 

35 

14 

$0  30 

$0  31                                       .     .. 

1 
1 

14 
2 

1 

1 

1 
1 
8 

1 

1 

$0.32 

1 
10 

1 

$0.33 

4 

$0.34 

1 

$0  35 

1 

$0  36 

$0.37                     

2 
20 

1 

i 

6 

1 
20 

1 

$0.39 

14 

$0  40 

1 

$0  43 

1 

1 
1 

$0  45 

$0  50 

Total       .- 

103 

103 

61 

61 

42 

42 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

Table  23. — Retail  prices  of  cold  remedy,  nationally  advertised  brand  and  substitute 
brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores,  June  19S9 


Price 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 


Total 


Nationally 

advertised 

brand 


Substitute 
brands 


Chain  stores 


Nationally 

advertised 

brand 


Substitute 
brands 


Independent  stores 


Nationally 

advertised 

brand 


Substitute 
brands 


$0.19. 
$0.21. 
$0.23. 
$0.24. 
$0.25. 
$0.27. 
$0.28. 
$0.29. 
$0.30. 
$0.31. 
$0.33. 
$0.36. 
$0.60. 


Total. 


60 


Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


60 


42 


374  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  24. — Retail  prices  of  vitamin  product,  nationally  advertised  brand  and  substitute 
brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores,  June  1939 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 

Price 

Total 

Chain  stores 

Independent  stores 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

$0  23                                   .       - 

1 

1 
8 
6 
8 
2 
20 
1 
9 
4 
1 

1 
1 
3 
4 
6 

$0  49                                       .  --- 

$0.59               

■5- 

$0.65      

1 

$0  69 

2 

$0.75                        

2 

$0.79        

67 

36 

16 

21 

4 

$0  80 

1 

$0.89          

3 

3 
2 

3 

6 

$0.98 

2 

$0  99 

1 

Total 

60 

60 

36 

36 

24 

24 

Scarce:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


Table  25. — Retail  prices  of  liquid  laxative  "B",  nationally  advertised  brand  and  sub- 
stitute brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores,  June  1939 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 

Retail  price 

Total 

Chain  stores 

Independent  stores 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

$0.10 

1 

7 
2 
1 
5 
5 
1 
4 
37 

1 

$5.15 

5 
2 
1 
2 

4 
1 
3 
16 

2 

$0.17 

$0.18 

$0.19 

3 

$0.20 

1 

$0.21 

$0.23 

41 
21 

1 

24 
9 

1 

17 
12 

1 

$0.25 

21 

$0.26 

Total 

63 

63 

34 

34 

29 

29^ 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


375 


Table  26. — Retail  prices  of  oral  antiseptic,  nationally  advertised  brand  and  substitute 
brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores,  June  1939 


Number  of  stores  reporting  specified  prices 

Retail  price 

Total 

Chain  stores 

Independent  stores 

Nationally  i  c!.,K,.tit.,t„ 

advertised     ^^l'^,!'^."*^ 

brand            ^"^^^^^ 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Substitute 
brands 

$9.19. _ 

3 
1 
6 

1 
1 
1 

20 
2 
1 
1 
1 

67 
5 
1 
1 
1 
1 

2 

1 

$0.25                                 -.     

1 

$0.29 , 

2 

1 

4 

S0.32    

$0.33 

1 

$0.37 -.-. 

1 

.$0.39 

6 
2 
1 
1 
1 
49 

14 

$0.40 .       ..     -. 

$0.44 

.$0.45 

.$0.48        .       -       - 

.$0.49  ...              .          ... 

18 

$0.,'iO 

5 

$0.59 

112 
2 

66 

1 

46 
2 

.$0.69      " 

1 

$0.88 

1 

$0.89 .       .. 

1 

Total 

114                   114 

66                   66 

48 

48 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

Although  the  nationally  advertised  merchandise  and  the  private 
brands  were  in  each  case  very  similar,  it  should  not  be  assumed  that 
there  were  no  significant  differences  in  quality  which  might  account  in 
whole  or  in  part  for  the  price  differentials.  The  analgesic  tablets, 
shown  in  table  19,  and  the  liquid  laxative,  in  table  22  are  both  stand- 
ard commodities  described  in  the  pharmacopoeia  but  the  other  item.s 
tabulated  were  less  uniform  in  character. 

In  the  case  of  the  analgesic  tablets  (table  19),  the  price  most  com- 
monly quoted  for  substitute  brands  both  by  chain  stores  and  inde- 
pendents was  10  cents,  in  contrast  to  the  12-cent  minimum  price 
fixed  for  the  nationally  advertised  commodity.  Nine  of  the  60  chain 
stores  charged  less  than  10  cents  for  their  substitute  brands;  in  one 
case  the  quotation  was  as  low  as  2  cents  for  a  dozen  tablets.  Inde- 
pendent stores,  on  the  other  hand,  quoted  the  10-cent  price  almost 
uniformly  and  only  one  of  the  54  independent  outlets  went  below  this 
ievel. 

The  remaining  tables  in  this  group  are  generall.y  similar  in  character. 
In  the  case  of  the  drug  sundry,  the  typical  price  (the  rnodal  price) 
for  the  substitute  brands  was  17  cents  as  compared  with  the  l^Yi 
cent  and  20  cent  minima  established  for  the  advertised  variety.  The 
price  most  com.m.only  quoted  for  the  unadvertised  brand  of  the  shaving 
article  was  10  cents,  as  compared  with  25  cents  for  the  nationally 
known  brand.  Differences  of  this  kind  are  not  merely  the  results  of 
resale  price  maintenance;  the  price  most  commonly  charged  for  16 
ounces  of  the  unadvertised  brands  of  liquid  laxative  was  about  25 
percent  less  than  the  39-cent  level  at  which  the  nationally  advertised 
brand  is  generally  quoted.      (See  table  22.) 

The  remaining  tables  in  this  series  tell  a  very  similar  story.  In 
each  case  the  range  of  prices  as  well  as  the  price  most  frequently 


247140—41 — No.  1- 


-26 


376 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


charged  is  materially  higher  for  the  nationally  advertised  than  for  the 
substitute  brand.  However,  since  the  data  relate  to  products  for 
which  quality  is  quite  variable,  the  significance  of  these  comparisons 
should  not  be  exaggerated.  This  should  not  be  taken  to  mean  that 
the  nationally  advertised  item  is  necessarily  superior  in  quality  to 
that  of  the  unbranded  product,  but  simply  that  the  articles  are  not 
in  all  respects  identical  in  content  or  utility,  and  that  technical  analysis 
which  is  beyond  the  scope  of  this  discussion  would  be  needed  in  order 
to  appraise  the  full  significance  of  price  differentials.  What  these 
figures  do  emphasize  is  the  difficulty  confronting  the  consumer  in 
choosing  intelligently  among  rival  commodities  of  this  character  and 
the  vii'tual  impossibility  of  translating  differences  of  price  into  terms 
of  intrinsic  utility. 

It  may  also  be  observed  that  chain  stores  report  prices  for  substitute 
brands  more  frequently  than  do  independent  stores.  This  is  only 
natural  because  the  promotion  of  a  private  brand  often  requires 
resources  beyond  the  command  of  the  individual  druggist. 

An  additional  comparison  may  be  made  of  the  prices  and  price 
trends  of  nationally  advertised  and  private  label  merchandise  quoted 
by  mail  order  houses  in  their  catalogs.  Tables  27  to  30  are  for  the 
same  products  as  those  shown  in  tables  1,  2,  3,  and  4  respectively, 
except  that  the  analgesic  tablets  (table  27)  are  quoted  in  units  of  100, 
rather  than  per  dozen. 


Table   27. 


-Retail   prices   of  analgesic   tablets,    nationally    advertised   brand   and 
distributors'  brands,  charged  by  two  mail-order  houses 


«  Tin  of  12  free. 

Source:  Mail-order  catalogs. 


Retail  prices  listed  for  designated  periods 

Date  of  catalog 

Mail-order  house  "A" 

Mail-order  house  "B" 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Distribu- 
tor's brand 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Distribu- 
tor's pri- 
mary brand 

Distribu- 
tor's secon- 
dary brand 

192*— spring  and  summer 

$0  98 

$0.59 
.59 
.61 
.58 
.58 
.58 
.58 
.58 
.49 
.44 
.44 
.38 
.38 
.19 
.19 
.19 
.19 
.19 
,17 
.16 
.16 
.16 
.16 

1929-30— fall  and  winter.. 

97 
98 
98 
98 
98 
95 
95 
73 
69 
69 
59 
59 
44 
49 
49 
59 
59 
59 
59 
59 
59 

■in 

1930— spring  and  summer 

1930-31— fall  and  winter .. 

1931— spring  and  summer 

1931-32— fall  and  winter 

1932— spring  and  summer.^.  >::.' 

$0.95 

$0.58 

1932-33— fall  and  winter  .. 

1933— sprine  and  summer 

.73 
.69 
.69 
.59 
.59 
.44 
.49 
.59 
.59 
.59 
.59 
.59 
.59 
.59 
.59 

.49 
.44 
.44 
.44 
1.38 
1.38 
>.38 
».38 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.29 

1933-34— fall  and  winter.  ...    .. 

1934— spring  and  summer 

1934-35— fall  and  winter . 

$0.28 
19 

1935— spring  and  summer 

193.'>-3»>— fall  and  winter... 

.19 

1936— spring  and  summer 

.19 

1930-37— fall  and  winter     . 

19 

1937— spring  and  summer 

19 

1937-38-fall  and  winter 

.19 

1938— spring  and  summer..     .. 

.18 

1938-39— fall  and  winter.. 

16 

1939— spring  and  summer 

16 

1939-10— fall  and  winter  ..     .. 

16 

1940— spring  aad  summer.. 

16 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


377 


Table   28. 


-Retail   prices   of   a   drug  sundry,    nationally    advertised    brand    and 
distributors'  brands,  charged  by  two  mail-order  houses 


Retail  prices  listed  for  designated  periods 

Date  of  catalog 

Mail-order  house  "A" 

Mail-order  house  "B" 

Nationally  adver- 
tised brand 

Distributor's 
brand 

Nationally  adver- 
tised brand 

Distributor's 
brand 

1929 — spring  and  summer 

Each  $0.37 

do 

Each  $0.27 

1929-30— fall  and  winter _ 

Each  $0.28 

1930 — spring  and  summer 

Each  $0.39 

Each  $0.35 

do 

Each  $0.27  .   . 

1930-31— fall  and  winter 

Each  $0.29 

1931 — spring  and  summer 

do 

1931-32— fall  and  winter..     

.do.     . 

-..do.     . 

1932 — spring  and  summer .  . 

3  for  $0.78 -. 

3  for  $0.79 _ 

3  for  $0.63 

3  for  $0.59 

3  for  $0.54 

3  for  $0.47 

3  for  $0.49 

2for$0.35 

..     .do-- 

3  for  $0.59 

3  for  $0.54 

3  for  $0.70 

5  for  $0.98. 

1932-33— fall  and  winter 

1933 — spring  and  summer  ... 

3  for  $0.39 

do 

3  for  $0.44 

3  for  $0.42 

3  for  $0.39 

2  tor  $0.28 

..  .do. 

3  for  $0.79 

3  for  $0.59 

3  for  $0.54 

3  for  $0.47 

3  for  $0.49 

2  for  $0.35 

do 

.do--   .  . 

3  for  $0.48. 

1933-34— fall  and  winter  

3  for  $0.45. 

1984 — spring  and  summer. 

Do. 

1934-35 — fall  and  winter 

3  for  $0.39 

1935 — spring  and  summer       

3  for  $0.25. 

1935-36 — fall  and  winter  

2  for  $0.28. 

1936— sprine  and  summer.   .. 

Do. 

1936-37— fall  and  winter 

.      do.- 

do 

Do. 

1937 — spring  and  summer 

2  for  $0.37.  . 

..do 

2  for  $0.37. 

2  for  $0.39 - 

do 

Do. 

1937-38— fall  and  winter.. 

2  for  $0.39. 

do 

2  for  $0.29 

2  for  $0.23 

2  for  $0.29. 

1938 — spring  and  summer 

2  for  $0.28. 

1938-39— fall  and  winter 

do 

..  do 

2  for  $0.21 

do.. 

Do. 

1939 — spring  and  summer 

2  for  $0.24... 

do 

Do. 

1939-40— fall  and  winter  . 

.    .do 

2  for  $0.23 

....do.     

Do. 

1940 — spring  and  snmmfir 

do 

2  for  $0.26 

do 

2  for  $0.29. 

Source:  Mail-order  catalogs. 

Table  29. — Retail  prices  of  liquid  laxative  "A,"  nationally  advertised  brand  and 
distributors'  brands,  charged  by  2  mail-order  houses 


Retail  prices  listed  for  designated  periods 

Date  of  catalog 

Mail-order  house  "A" 

Mail-order  house  "B" 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Distribu- 
tor's brand 

Nationally 

advertised 

brand 

Distribu- 
tor's pri- 
mary brand 

Distribu- 
tor's secon- 
dary brand 

$0.38 
.38 
.42 
.39 
.39 
.39 
.39 
.39 
.39 
.37 
.39 
.36 
.36 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.34 
.34 
.34 
.34 
.34 
.34 

1929-30 — fall  and  winter 

1931-32 — fall  and  winter 

$0.39 

1932-33 — fall  and  winter 

$0.24 
.22 
.29 
.24 
.24 
.27 
.27 
.27 
.27 
.27 
.21 
.21 
.21 
.24 
.27 

.39 
.37 
.39 
.36 
.36 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.34 
.34 
.34 
.34 
.34 
.34 

$6.31 
.28 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.27 
.27 
.27 
.27 
.27 
.27 
.27 
.24 
.24 
.27 

1934-35 — fall  and  winter     

$0.24 

1935 — spring  and  summer 

.24 

1935-36 — fall  and  winter 

.19 

.23 

1936-37— fall  and  winter       

.23 

1937 — spring  and  summer 

.23 

1937-38— fall  and  winter         

.23 

.23 

1938-39— fall  and  wintrr 

.21 

1939 — spring  and  summer         

.21 

Source:  Mail-order  catalogs. 


378  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  30. — Retail  prices  of  liquid  laxative  "B,"  nationally  advertised  brand  and 
tstributors'  brands,  charged  by  2  mail-order  houses 


Date  of  catalog 


Retail  prices  listed  for  designated  periods 


Mail-order  hoa'^e  "A" 


Nationally 

advertised 

brand 


Distribu- 
tor's brand 


Mail-order  house  "B' 


Nationally 

advertised 

brand 


Distribu- 
tor's brand 


1929 — sprin?  and 
1929-30— fall  and 
1930— spriu^;  and 
1930-31— fall  and 
1931— spring  and 
1931-32— fall  and 
1932— spring  and 
1932-33— fall  and 
1933— spring  and 
1933-34— fall  and 
1934— spring  and 
1934-35— fall  and 
1915— spring  and 
1935-36-fall  and 
1936— spring  and 
1936-37— fall  and 
1937— spring  and 
1937-38— fall  and 
1938— spring  and 
1938-39— fall  and 
1939— spring  and 
1939-40— fall  and 
1940— spring  and 


summer.. 
winter..: 
summer, 
winter... 
summer., 
winter... 
summer, 
winter... 
summer, 
winter... 
summer, 
winter... 
summer, 
winter... 
summer, 
winter... 
summer, 
winter... 
summer, 
winter. .. 
summer, 
winter... 
summer. 


$0.42 
.42 
.42 
.42 
.39 
.39 
.34 
.34 
.34 
.34 
.34 
.34 
.47 
.47 


$0.25 
.25 
.29 
.31 
.31 
.31 
.31 
.31 
.31 
.29 
.31 
.27 
.27 
.27 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.21 
.21 
.21 
.21 
.23 


$0.42 


$0.31 


.31 
.2£ 
.31 
.29 
.27 
.27 
.29 
.27 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.29 
.29 


Source:  Mail-order  catalogs. 

In  each  case  the  items  sold  under  the  private  label  are  materially 
cheaper  than  the  nationally  advertised  brand.  The  contrast  is 
particularly  striking  for  the  analgesic  tablets  which  contain,  as  has 
been  stated,  the  identical  active  ingredients.  It  is  also  noteworthy 
that  the  price  of  the  private-label  tablets  has  declined  much  more 
sharply  since  1929  than  has  that  of  the  nationally  advertised  item  and 
that  this  difference  in  trend  became  particulariy  marked  after  the 
introduction  of  resale  price  maintenance. 

Table  31  shows  the  relationship  between  the  prices  charged  for  a 
nationally  advertised  and  a  substitute  brand  of  liquid  laxative  (the 
one  shown  in  table  5  above)  by  individual  stores.  This  product  is 
the  onlv  one  suitable  for  comparison  of  this  kind  because  of  the  effect 
of  resale  price  maintenance  in  limiting  the  price  variability  of  the 
nianufacturers'  brands  for  all  the  other  products  which  have  been 
discussed.  The  nationally  advertised  brand  is  in  a  12-ounce  package, 
while  substitute  brands  are  quoted  in  16-ounce  quantities.  This 
table  indicates  a  wide  diversity  of  practice  between  stores.  For 
example,  there  are  15  chain  stores  quoting  39  cents  for  the  nationally 
advertised  brand;  one  of  these  offers  a  substitute  for  as  httle  as  11 
cents,  and  three  charge  the  same  price  for  the  substitute  brand  as  for 
the  advertised  product.  Seventeen  of  the  chain  stores  which  quote 
a  34-cent  price  for  the  national  brand,  charge  29  cents  for  the  sub- 
stitute, but  the  other  six  charge  prices  ranging  from  19  cents  to  39 
c^nts.  Eight  of  the  stores  actually  charge  more  for  the  substitute 
than  for  the  advertised  brand,  but  it  should  be  remembered  that  the 
latter  contains  three-;fourths  of  the  quantity  of  the  former.  There  is 
no  apparent  correlation  between  prices  for  the  two  varieties;  thus  it 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


379 


happens  that  the  lowest  price  reported  for  a  substitute  brand  is  by  a 
store  which  charges  the  top  price  for  the  national  brand. 

Independent  stores  show  a  slightly  greater  correlation  between 
prices  for  the  national  and  the  substitute  brands.  Stores  charging 
low  prices  for  the  former  usually  also  charge  low  prices  for  the  latter 
and  vice  versa.  In  general,  however,  there  is  little  uniformity  of 
practice,  and  the  price  charged  by  a  store  for  nationally  advertised 
merchandise  affords  no  guide  to  the  prices  at  which  substitute  brands 
are  offered. 


Table  31. — Retail  prices  of  liquid  laxative  "A",  nationally  advertised  and  substitute 
brands,  in  chain  and  independent  stores — June  19S9 


CHAIN  STORES 

Retail  prices 
for  nation- 

Retail prices  for  substitute  brands— 16  ounc  s 

ally  adver- 
tised brand— 
12  ounces 

$0.11 

$0.19 

$0.23 

$0.25 

$0.27 

$0.29 

$0.32 

$0.33 

$0.34 

$0.37 

$0.39 

Total 

^.39 .- 

1 

8 

1 

1 
2 

1 

3 

1 

15 

$0.37 .... 

1 

4 

$0.36         .  . 

1 

1 

$0.35    

1 
2 

1 

$0.34 

1 

1 

17 
3 

1 

1 

23 

$0.33. 

3 

$0.32 

1 

1 

■$0.31 

2 

1 

3 

$0.30 

1 
2 

1 

$0.29 

3 
1 

2 

7 

$0.28     

1 

$0.25 

1 

1 

Total... 

1 

1 

1 

1 

3 

35 

1 

10 

1 

1 

6 

61 

INDEPENDENT  STORES 


Retail  prices 
for  natioot 

Retail  prices  for  substitute  brands— 16  ounces 

ally  adver- 
tised brand— 
12  ounces 

$0.19 

$0.23 

$0.25 

$0.29 

$0.31 

$0.33 

$0.34 

$0.35 

$0.37 

$0.39 

$0.40 

Total 

10.50       .-    .. 

1 

$0.45 

1 

$0.43 

1 
9 
1 
1 

1 

i' 

$0.39 

1 

7 

2 

1 

21 

$0.37 

$0.35 

$0.34 

1 

4 

1 
1 

1 

8 

$0.33 

$0  32 

1 

$0  31 

i 

$0  29 

2 

1 

$0  28 

1 

$0  24 

1 

Total... 

1 

1 

3 

14 

1 

4 

1 

1 

1 

14 

1 

42 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

Substitute  brands  and  resale  price  maintenance. — During  the  past 
few  years,  the  relationship  between  nationally  advertised  merchandise 
and  private  label  or  substitute  brands  has  been  affected  by  the  spread 
of  resale  price  maintenance  legislation.  When  minimum  resale  prices 
are  established  for  manufacturers'  advertised  brands,  it  is  evident 
that  retailers  who  depend  largely  upon  price  appeal  must  shift  their 
price-cutting  emphasis  to  articles  which  are  not  subject  to  such 


QgQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

restrictions — either  to  their  own  private  brands  or  to  other  kinds  of 
products.  Some  of  the  larger  distributors,  who  had  always  featured 
a  policy  of  offering  low  prices,  apparently  seized  the  opportunity  to 
stress  the  savings  available  to  the  consumer  on  purchases  of  their  own 
brands.  For  example,  a  large  New  York  City  department  store  and 
some  of  the  leading  mail-order  houses  have  published  advertisements 
comparing  the  prices  of  nationally  advertised  products  with  those  of 
their  own  brands,  coupled  with  reports  of  analyses  purporting  to  show 
that  the  two  are,  in  fact,  identical  in  quality.  More  recently  this 
policy  of  comparative  advertising  has  been  somewhat  modified, 
possibly  because  of  pressure  from  the  manufacturers  of  the  nationally 
advertised  articles. 

On  the  other  hand,  there  is  also  some  evidence  that  the  availability 
of  wide  guaranteed  margins  on  nationally  advertised  price-maintained 
products  has  lessened  the  interest  of  some  large  distributors  in  pushing 
their  own  private  brands.  During  September  1939,  for  example,  the 
Nevins  Drug  Chain  in  Philadelphia  announced  a  major  reversal  in 
sales  policy  and  instructed  its  clerks  to  refrain  from  attempting  to 
"switch"  customers  from  nationally  advertised  brands  to  private, 
brands.  Thus,  according  to  the  Drug  Trade  News  of  September 
25,  1939: 

Because  a  month's  test  proved,  statistically,  that  switching  from  nationally 
advertised  brands  to  private  brands  does  not  pay,  the  Nevins  Drug  Co.  of  this 
city,  operator  of  63  stores  in  Pennsylvania,  Maryland,  and  New  Jersey,  has  just 
instituted  an  iron-bound  policy  rigorously  prohibiting  the  practice  of  switching 
in  its  stores. 

******* 

"Under  our  State  fair-trade  law,"  Mr.  Sylk  (a  partner  of  the  firm)  also  pointed 
out,  "it  does  not  pay  us — and  we  imagine  the  same  thing  would  hold  true  for 
others — to  go  to  all  the  trouble  of  switching  customers.  Our  present  figures  eshow 
conclusively  that  less  profit  is  made  today  on  private  brand  goods  than  on 
nationally  advertised  items.  We  find  that,  when  switching  is  resorted  to,  there  is 
an  immediate  reduction  in  sales  volume." 

Similar  considerations  apply  even  more  forcibly  to  independent 
retailers.  During  the  past  few  years  retail  trade  associations  and 
manufacturers  of  well-known'  brands  have  sponsored  an  annual 
"National  Brands  Week"  featuring  a  concerted  drive  to  sell  widely 
advertised  brands,  particularly  those  which  were  selling  under  price 
maintenance  contracts.  The  issues  involved  in  this  alliance  are 
suggested  in  two  articles  which  appeared  simultaneously  in  the 
July  1939  issue  of  the  American  Druggist,  a  recognized  organ  of  the 
drug  trade. 

The  first  of  these  articles  described  the  results  of  a  survey  conducted 
by  the  students  of  Mississippi  State  College  to  determine  the  attitude 
of  drug  sales  clerks  toward  advertised  and  substitute  brands.  Quoting 
from  this  article:  ^ 

Out  of  568  retail  salespersons  in  the  drug  field,  only  187,  or  33%,  believe  that 
nationally-advertised  brands  are  worth  their  higher  prices. 

This  was  the  outstanding  fact  brought  to  light  by  the  marketing  survey  of 
students  of  Mississippi  State  College  in  one  of  their  recent  surveys.  These 
students  had  been  studying  the  attitudes  of  manufacturers,  distributors,  and 
consumers  toward  fair-trade  laws,  but  could  find  little  about  the  retail  salesperson. 
So,  an  investigation  was  planned  to  find  out  just  what  this  individual  thinks  about 
price  dififerentials.  After  all,  the  sales  clerk  in  the  store  is  the  salesperson  who 
deals  directly  with  the  consumer. 

'  American  Druggist,  July  1939,  vol.  C,  No.  1,  p.  40. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


381 


During  the  spring  holidays,  students  went  into  568  drug  stores  in  96  cities  and 
towns.  Mississippi  localities  dominated,  yet  seven  other  States  were  repre- 
sented, Alabama,  Louisiana,  Tennessee,  Georgia,  Florida,  Texas,  and  Arkansas. 
Of  the  568  stores,  284  were  independent  and  284  were  chain  stores. 

Upon  entering  a  store,  each  student  established  the  fact,  in  conversation  with  a 
salesperson,  that  a  price  differential  existed  between  some  nationally  advertised 
brand  and  a  lesser-known  brand  (private,  regional,  or  nonadvertised).  Products 
compared  were  always  of  identical  quantity. 

The  student  then  asked  the  sales  clerk  in  a  single  question,  using  these  exact 
words,  "Is  X  (the  nationally  advertised  brand)  worth  the  higher  price?" 

In  the  following  tabulations,  "No"  means  that  the  salesperson  said  the 
nationally  advertised  item'  wag  not  worth  the  higher  price,  but  offered  no  explana- 
tion or  amplification.  The  second  group,  "No — advertising,"  covers  answers  in 
which  the  clerk  said  that  advertising  expenditures  caused  the  nationally  known 
products  to  be  higher  priced.  "No — quality  same"  needs  no  explanation.  The 
fourth  group,  "No — container"  consists  of  replies  that  attributed  the  higher 
price  of  the  nationally  advertised  brand  to  a  container.  The  final  negative  group 
is  made  up  of  answers  that  side-stepped  the  question. 

Affirmative  answers  are  of  two  types.  "Yes"  means  that  the  clerks  said 
merely  that  the  nationally  advertised  brand  was  worth  the  higher  price.  Answers 
which  contained  justifications  for  higher  prices  were  put  in  the  "Yes"  group. 


This  listing  is  for  568  replies 

Independent  and  chain  answers  split 
this  way 

Negative  replies  for  each  of  6  products 
mentioned  in  survey 

Answer 

Number 

of 
replies 

Answer 

Inde- 
pendent 

Chain 

Item 

Negative  replies 
from— 

Inde- 
pendent 

Chain 

"No"             .      . 

110 
85 

139 

2 

45 

"No". 

49 
41 

59 

61 
44 

80 

2 

24 

Aspirin^   ..  . 

Percent 
58 
82 

73 
44 
50 
64 

Percent 

84 

"No"    (advertis- 
ing). 

"No""     (quality 
same). 

"No"     (contain- 

"No" (advertis- 
ing). 

"No"    (quality 
same). 

"No"  (contain- 
er). 

Evasive 

Total  "No". 

"Yes" 

"Yes"  (quality) - 

Total  "Yes" 

Total 

Milk    of    mag- 
nesia. 

Mouthwash 

Shaving  cream.. 
Soap    

87 

69 
76 
55 

er). 
Evasive 

21 

Toothpaste 

75 

Total  "No".. 

381 

170 

211 

"Yes" 

"Yes"  (quality).. 

64 
123 

43 
71 

21 
52 

Total  "Yes". 

187 

114 

73 

Total 

568 

284 

284 

The  second  article  was  an  editorial  comment  upon  the  situation 
disclosed  in  the  survey. 

It  is  a  startling  and  unexpected  peril  to  the  cause  of  fair  trade  that  Dr.  A.  C. 
Kirkpatrick,  assistant  professor  of  business  administration  at  Mississippi  State 
College,  exposes  in  his  special  article  appearing  on  page  40  of  this  issue  of  American 
Druggist. 

Mississippi  State  College  students  of  marketing  conducting  an  importial  survey 
among  retail  drug  sales  clerks  in  eight  Southern  States,  have  brought  to  light  the 
appalling  fact  that  two-thirds  of  these  sales  people — those  individuals  who  come 
in  direct  contact  with  the  ultimate  consumer— are  belittling  nationally  advertised 
products  by  word  of  mouth  "over  the  counter." 

Whether  in  individual  cases  this  destructive  propaganda  has  been  deliberate 
or  whether  it  has  been  the  result  of  indifference  or  plain  ignorance  on  the  part 
of  clerks,  the  significant  point  is  that  a  majority  of  retail  drug  sales  people  in  the 
area  covered  ,by  the  surv6y  have  been  telling  customers  that  costs  of  prornotion, 
exploitation,  containers,  and  other  extraneous  factors  boost  the  prices  of  nationally 
advertised  brands  which  intrinsically  are  of  no  better  quality  than  'ess  well-known 
pi-ivate,  regional,  or  nonadvertised  products. 


2g2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Under  any  circumstances,  such  statements  on  the  part  of  a  large  number  of 
retail  sales  clerks  over  so  wide  a  region  would  constitute  an  alarming  threat  to  the 
drug  industry  as  a  whole,  particularly  to  manufacturers  and  distributors  of 
nationally  known  brands.  Right  now,  with  fair  trade  in  a  precarious  position, 
they  constitute  a  menace  to  the  retail  pharmacist  himself,,  as  well. 

Fair  trade  is  the  independent  retail  pharmacist's  own  baby.  It  was  the  retail 
pharmacist,  through  his  own  State  and  national  organizations,  who  fought  tooth 
and  nail  for  a  law  that  would  enable  him  to  compete  on  an  equal  footing  with  his 
cut-rate  and  other  competitors.  Today  manufacturers  and  wholesalers  are  allied 
with  the  retailer  in  battling  for  the  preservation  of  fair  trade  where  it  has  been 
enacted  and  for  its  extension  into  States  where  it  has  been  so  far  denied. 

******* 

Here  is  a  real — and  perhaps  the  most  vital — danger  to  what  pharmacy  has 
accomplished  with  such  an  heroic  effort  and  is  defending  so  doggedly  at  this 
moment.  The  drug  clerk  and  his  influencp  op  public  and  consequently  on  legis- 
lative opinion  has  been  overlooked.  Do  you  know  what  your  clerks  are  telling 
your  own  customers  about  fair-trade  prices  these  days? 

It  is  up  to  the  owners  of  pharmacies  to  see  that  their  clerks  are  instructed  in 
the  beneficial  facts  of  fair  trade"  so  that  they  may  buil-d  goodwill  among  your 
voter-customers  instead  of  destroying  it.  It  is  up  to  State  and  national  pharma- 
ceutical organizations  and  associations  to  impress  upon  their  members  the  neces- 
sity of  getting  their  own  employees  into  line  behind  fair  trade. 

That  is — unless  pharmacy  has  made  up  its  mind  to  let  the  fair-t  >ide  ship  sink 
ai\d  to  wallow  again  in  the  murky  turmoil  of  unregulated,  cut-throat  competition 
which  formerly  engulfed  the  independent  retailer.  American  Druggist  aoes  not 
believe  pharmacy  is  willing  to  give  up  the  ship  so  readily. 

But  a  ship  cannot  sail  without  the  loyalty  of  the  crew — and  clerks  who  sell 
your  goods  over  the  counter  are  the  crew  of  the  ship  of  fair  trade. 

Is  it  good  business  to  tolerate  mutiny  on  the  "Bounty" — whether  deliberate  or 
unintentional?  * 

PRICE    LINES 

Retail  prices  charged  for  drugs,  toiletries,  and  sundries  are  to  some 
extent  affected  by  the  institution  of  price  lines  which  was  described 
in  detail  in  part  I  of  this  volume.®  Price  lines  for  this  group  of  prod- 
ucts are  much  less  uniformly  observed  than  in  the  case  of  such  arti- 
cles as  women's  apparel;  nevertheless  they  do  have  a  certain  broad 
effect  upon  the  market. 

As  mentioned  earlier,  the  retail  list  prices  of  these  products  are 
usually  in  even  figures.  For  items  selling  for  $1  or  less,  list  prices 
are  usually  in  multiples  of  25  cents,  i.  e.,  $1,  75  cents,  50  cents,  or  25 
cents.     In  addition,  35  cents  is  an  important  intermediate  line. 

In  contrast,  contractual  minimum  prices,  except  when  these  are 
set  at  the  full  list,  are  almost  invariably  at  odd  figures.  The  char- 
acter of  the  relation  between  full  list  and  minimum  prices  is  illus- 
trated in  ta,ble  32  below.  This  table  is  based  upon  the  published 
list  and  minimum  prices  of  a  leading  drug  manufacturer.  For 
example,  7  of  the  items  in  this  manufacturer's  line  have  full  list 
prices  of  $1  and  contractual  minima  of  89  cents;  four  have  list  prices 
of  $1  with  minima  of  79  cents;  18  have  list  prices  of  25  cents  and 
minima  of  23  cents,  etc.  ,  For  82  of  the  121  items,  list  prices  are  at 
the  five  lines  which  have  been  described  as  most  common — $1,  75 
cents,  50  cents,  35  cents,  and  25  cents.  For  no  single  item  selling 
above  10  cents,  on  the  other  hand,  has  the  minimum  price  been 
established  at  an  even  multiple  of  5  cents. 

•  Ibid.,  p.  25. 

•  See  supra,  pp.  242-261. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


383 


Table  32. — Comparison  of  full  list  prices  with  contractual  minimum  prices 
[Full  list  prices,  in  dollars] 


Contractual 
minimum 
(in  dollars) 

1.00 

0.90 

0.85 

0.75 

0.70 

0.65 

0.60 

o.to 

a  46 

0.40 

0.35 

0.30 

0.25 

0.20 

0.16 

0.12 

0.10 

Total 

0.89 

7 
4 

7 

0.79 

1 

6 

0.74 

1 

1 

0.69 

8 
4 

g. 

0.59 

— - 

1 
1 
3 

5 

0.57 

3 

4 

0.53 

3 

0.49 - 

1 

3 

1 

6 

7 
1 
2 

5 

0.47 

6 

0.43- 

7 

0.41 

1 

2 

0.39 

1 

.... 

3 

0.37 

2 

2 

0.33 

4 
4 
7 
1 

4 

0.31 

3 

7 

0.29 

1 
1 

8 

0.27 ..^^... 

. 

2 

0.23.. „..-. 

18 
2 
3 
3 

18 

0.22 

2 

0.21 

3 

0.19 

5 
2 
1 

8 

0.17.    . 

2 

0.16 

1 

0.13 

4 

4 

0.10- 

1 

3 

4 

Total........ 

11 

1 

1 

12 

1 

6 

6 

17 

1 

5 

16 

2 

26 

8 

4 

1 

3 

121 

Source:  Published  price  list  of  a  well-known  drug  manufacturer. 

The  difference  between  the  list  prices  and  minimum  prices  of  in- 
dividual items  varies  considerably,  depending,  at  least  in  part,  upon 
the  character  of  the  item  and  the  extent  to  which  it  is  used  as  a  price 
leader.  The  maximum  differential  is  usually  20  percent  plus  1 
cent.  This  is  the  exact  relation  existing  between  the  following 
combinations  of  list  and  minimum  prices: 


Number  of  items 

List  price 

Minimum 
price 

Number  of  items 

List  price 

Minimum 
price 

4 

$1.00 
.75 
.50 

$0.79 
.59 
.39 

3 

$.40 
.35 
.25 

$0.31 

4 

1 

.27 

2 

3 - 

.19 

In  only  two  cases,  a  70-cent  it«m  with  a  minimum  of  49  cents  and  a 
65-cent  item  with  a  minimum  of  39  cents,  Was  the  difference  between 
the  full  list  and  the  minimum  price  wider  than  21  percent.  Both  of 
these  items  are  toiletries  of  a  kind  which  are  particularly  subject  to 
severe  price  cutting. 

For  the  bulk  of  the  items  sold  by  this  manufacturer,  however,  the 
differential  between  the  full  list  price  and  the  minimum  price  was  much 
narrower,  in  many  cases  ranging  from  1  to  3  cents.  The  most  frequent 
single  situation  was  in  the  case  of  18  items  whose  full  list  price  was 
25  cents  and  for  which  the  minimum  price  was  23  cents. 

In  the  case  of  expensive  cosmetics — those  selling  for  $1  and  rnore — 
minimum  prices  are  usually  fixed  at  the  full  list.     For  these  items, 


334  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

therefore,  price  lines  are  usually  at  even  figures:  e.  g.,  $1,  $1.50, 
$3.75,  $5,  etc.  In  the  range  below  $1,  minimum  prices  for  cosmetics 
are  also  often  at  the  full  list,  or  else  1  to  3  cents  below  it. 

With  regard  to  the  prices  actually  charged  by  retailers,  as  distinct 
from  the  list  prices  or  minimiun  prices  established  by  manufacturers, 
there  is  no  very  consistent  tendency  toward  the  observance  of  any 
definite  price  lines.  Table  33  indicates  the  frequency  with  which 
particular  prices  were  reported  to  the  bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  for 
14  different  drug  store  items  during  June  1939.  The  frequency  dis- 
tribution is  shown  separately  for  chain  stores  and  independents  and 
for  nationally  advertised  and  substitute  brands.  The  table  is  limited 
to  items  selling  between  10  cents  and  50  cents  because  there  are  not 
enough  quotations  above  or  below  these  levels  to  provide  any  satis- 
factory indication  of  the  practices  observed.  However,  it  may  be 
mentioned  that  a  great  majority  of  the  quotations  between  50  cents 
and  $1  were  at  three  prices,  which  were,  in  order  of  frequency,  59  cents, 
55  cents,  and  79  cents. 

The  distribution  of  price  quotations  in  the  table  is,  of  course,  in- 
fluenced by  the  particular  items  for  which  these  prices  were  reported 
and  does  not  necessarily  represent  actual  pricing  practices  for  all  articles 
sold  by  drug  stores  within  this  price  range.  Nevertheless,  certain 
inferences  seem  warranted. 

For  all  items  and  outlets  combined,  there  are  only  two  prices — 
25  cents  and  39  cents — which  accounted  for  more  than  10  percent  of 
the  total  number  of  quotations.  Six  other  lines — 10  cents,  20  cents. 
23  cents,  29  cents,  49  cents,  and  50  cents — each  represented  more 
than  5  percent  of  the  total  number  of  quotations.  These  eight  price 
line&,  together,  accounted  for  69  percent  of  the  total  number  of  prices 
quoted  in  the  10-cent  to  50-cent  range.  Chain  stores  appear  to  quote 
prices  in  odd  figures  somewhat  more  frequently  than  do  independents, 
both  for  nationally  advertised  and  for  substitute  products.  For 
example,  chain  stores  report  more  quotations  at  49  cents  than  at  50 
cents,  while  for  independents  the  relation  is  reversed.  The  25-cent 
price  line  is  also  more  commonly  observed  by  independents  than  by 
chain  stores,  whereas  the  former  reported  more  quotations  at  23  cents. 

In  summary ,  price  lines  evidently  play  some  part  in  the  retail  pricing 
practices  of  drug  stores.  Price  lines  at  odd  figures  seem  to  be  some- 
what more  characteristic  of  chain  stores  and  of  nationally  advertised 
brands,  while  even  figures  are  more  commonly  quoted  by  independent 
stores  and  for  substitute  or  unadvertised  brands.  (Prescriptions  are 
almost  invariably  priced  at  even  figures.)  However,  these  tendencies 
are  by  no  means  consistent  and  undoubtedly  reflect  the  choice  of  items 
included  in  the  tabulations,  so  that  no  clear  generalization  seems  war- 
ranted. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


385 


Table  33. — Distribution  of  retail  prices  quoted  by  drug  stores  for  13  items  selling 

between  10  and  50  cents 


Nationally  advertised  brands 

Substitute  brands 

Price  (in  cents) 

Total 

Chain  stores 

Independent 
stores 

Chain  stores    • 

Independent 
stores 

Num- 
ber of 
quota- 
tions 

Per- 
cent 

Num- 
ber of 
quota- 
tions 

Per- 
cent 

Num- 
ber of 
quota- 
tions 

Per- 
cent 

Num- 
ber of 
quota- 
tions 

Per- 
cent 

Num- 
ber of 
quota- 
tions 

Per- 
cent 

10 

167 

4 

107 

6 

14 

2 

6 

72 

6 

3 

2 

41 

23 

121 

10 

157 

39 

3 

172 

16 

497 

1 

110 

5 

210 

9 

15 

8 

64 

41 

34 

4 

23 

6 
(') 

4 
(') 
(') 
(') 
(') 

3 
(') 
(') 
(') 

1 
(') 

4 
(>) 

6 

1 
(') 

6 
(') 

18 
(') 

4 
(') 

8 
(') 
(') 
(') 

2 

1 

1 
0) 

o 

2 

(') 

27 

4 

72 
4 

10 
4 
6 
2 
3 

20 
4 

9 
(') 

1 
(0 
(■) 
(') 
(') 

3 
(') 

66 

12 

11,.. 

12  . 

62 

9 

33 

4 

2 
2 

1 

f) 
(') 
(') 

2/25 

13 

1 

(') 

6 

(') 

2/27 

14 

2 

5 

(') 
(') 

1 

30 

4 

15 

17 
2 
1 
2 
8 
3 

26 

3 

16-. 

(') 

2/33 

1 

(') 

1 

(') 

(') 

3/50 

(') 

17 

2 
9 
9 
8 

63 
6 
1 

55 

8 

101 

1 

60 
3 

42 
2 
6 
1 

19 

26 
2 
2 
7 

(0 

1 
1 
1 

9 
(') 
(') 

8 

1 

15 
(') 

9 
(') 

6 
(') 
(') 
(•) 

3 

4 
(') 
0) 

1 

1 

6 
22 

1 
74 

2 

(') 
(') 

3 
(') 

10 
(') 

30 
5 

64 
1 
9 
8 
2 

53 

5 

137 

4 
(•) 
8 

0) 
1 
1 

(') 
7 

(') 
17 

1 

18 

(') 

19 

5 

2/39  .. 

20 

ii 

23 

2 

21 -. 

4 

22 

^ 

48 

3 

147 

6 
(') 
20 

16 

3 

24 

25 

112 

20 

26 

27 

43 

2 

35 

5 
6 
4 

18 
9 

10 
1 

11 

6 

0) 
5 

(') 

(') 

(') 
2 
1 
1 

(') 
1 

6 

(') 

1 

(') 

28.... 

29 

88 

11 

45 
2 
1 

8 

30     

(') 

31 

2 
3 
21 
3 
8 

(') 
(') 
3 
"     (') 

1 

(') 

32 

33 

6 
3 
14 
1 
2 

1 

34- 

(') 

35     

3 

36 .. 

(') 

37 

3 

(') 

(') 

38 

39    

348 
6 
7 
4 
9 
6 
19 

13 

(>) 
(') 
(') 
(') 
(') 
(') 

120 

1 
5 
2 

1 
1 
3 

18 
(') 
(') 
(') 
(') 
(') 
0) 

116 

16 

47 
1 

6 
(') 

65 

4 

12 

40 -- 

(') 

41 

2 

(•) 

42            

2 
3 
3 
1 

(') 
(') 
(•) 
(') 

43     

4 
1 

7 

(') 
(') 
(') 

1 

1 
8 

(') 

44 

(') 

45 

1 

46 

47 

7 

3 

172 

178 

(') 

6 
6 

1 

(') 

4 

1 
26 
41- 

(') 

(') 
3 
5 

1 

2 

90 

64 

(') 

(') 
11 
8 

1 

(') 

48 

49 

20 
5 

3 

36 
68 

7 

50 

12 

Total. 

2,751 

665 

748 

787 

551 

'  Less  than  1  percent. 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 


CHAPTER  III 
DISTRIBUTIVE  MARGINS 

METHODS   OF  DISTRIBUTION 

Methods  of  distribution  in  the  drug  trade  are  fairly  well  defined. 
The  independent  retailer  buys  typically  from  a  full  service  wholesaler 
who  extends  credit  and  delivery  service  and  maintains  a  complete 
stock.  The  wholesaler,  in  turn,  buys  directly  from  the  manufacturer 
without  the  intervention  of  other  middlemen,  such  as  brokers  or  com- 
mission merchants.  Large  retailers  such  as  chain  stores,  mail-order 
houses,  and  department  stores  buy  most  of  their  products  directly 
from  the  manufacturers  but  in  some  cases  they,  too,  must  purchase 
through  wholesalers. 

The  precise  function  of  the  wholesale  merchant  varies  somewhat 
for  different  products.  A  number  of  manufacturers  of  widely  adver- 
tised merchandise  employ  their  own  salesmen  to  obtain  orders  from 
retailers  but  such  orders  are  almost  always  filled  by  the  local  whole- 
saler. Some  manufacturers  do  not  sell  their  merchandise  outright  to 
the  wholesaler  but  employ  him  in  the  capacity  of  a  del  credere  factor, 
that  is,  as  an  agent  who  is  empowered  to  sell  only  under  terms  specified 
by  the  manufacturer  but  who  also  assumes  any  credit  risks  on  the 
transaction. 

Many  drug  manufacturers  seek  to  exercise  control  over  resale  prices 
at  the  wholesale  as  well  as  at  the  retail  level.  Some  accomplish  this 
through  the  machinery  provided  under  the  price-maintenance  laws; 
they  issue  contracts  specifying  the  exact  terms  and  conditions  under 
which  the  wholesaler  may  sell  to  retailers.  Other  manufacturers 
utilize  the  factorship  arrangement  which  has  just  been  described, 
which  relegates  the  wholesaler  to  the  role  of  an  agent.  Still  other 
manufacturers  adopt  a  somewhat  more  flexible  policy;  they  suggest 
resale  terms  and  may  refuse  to  deal  with  wholesalers  who  do  not  con- 
form to  these  suggestions.  In  addition,  of  course,  many  manufac- 
turers make  no  effort  at  all  to  control  the  prices  charged  by  whole- 
salers. 

One  of  the  major  problems  confronting  the  drug  wholesaler  has 
already  been  suggested  in  the  preceding  discussion  of  retailing  prac- 
tices. The  variety  of  items  handled  by  the  retailer  is  so  great  that 
the  druggist  of  limited  capital  must  often  purchase  in  very  small  quan- 
tities. Thus  the  Department  of  Commerce  conducted  a  careful  survey 
of  the  operations  of  one  full  service  wholesale  merchant  during  1931. 
This  survey  showed  that  purchases  of  individual  commodities  by 
retailers  averaged  about  $2  per  line.     The  actual  figures  were:^ 

Prescription  department $1,  91 

Proprietary  remedies 1.  73 

Sundries -_ 2.  12 

Surgical  and  sickroom  supplies 1.  62 

Toilet  preparations 111."/. I     1.  46 

'  U.  S.  Department  of  Commerce,  Domestic  Commerce  Series  No.  86,  Wholesale  Druggists  Operations, 
386 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  3§7 

A  survey  conducted  by  the  National  Wholesale  Druggists  Associa- 
tion, reflecting  the  operations  of  two  wholesale  drug  houses,  showed 
that  about  45  percent  of  all  transactions  involved  sales  of  less  than 
$1  per  line  and  that  70  percent  involved  line  extensions  of  less  than  $2.^ 

This  situation  obviously  entails  high-cost  operation.  According  to 
the  Census  of  Wholesale  Distribution,  operating  expenses  for  full-line 
drug  wholesalers  in  1935  averaged  13  percent  of  sales;  for  drug  retailers 
operating  expenses  were  about  24  percent  of  sales.^ 

The  gross  margin  or  mark-up  actually  obtained  by  the  distributor 
on  the  sale  of  any  product  will,  of  course,  depend  upon  the  terms  at 
which  he  purchases  and  the  price  at  which  he  resells.  In  the  case  of 
some  products  handled  by  the  drug  trade,  a  one-price  system  is  ob- 
served at  each  stage  of  distribution.  The  wholesaler  pays  the  same 
price,  regardless  of  the  quantities  he  purchases,  and  is  bound  by  con- 
tract or  perhaps  by  a  factorship  arrangement  to  resell  to  all  retailers 
at  a  single  specified  price.  The  price  to  consumers  is  also  fixed  by 
contract,  with  the  minimum  established  at  the  full  list  price,  so  that 
again  there  is  no  room  for  variation.  In  most  cases  this  policy  will 
be  modified  somewhat,  insofar  as  wholesalers  and  retailers  are  con- 
cerned, by  the  availability  of  optional  cash  discounts,  but  these  are 
usually  limited  to  1  or  2  percent. 

In  the  case  of  most  items  handled  by  the  drug  trade,  however,  the 
situation  is  far  less  simple.  Discounts  on  quantity  purchases  are 
available  both  to  wholesalers  and  retailers.  Minimum  resale  prices 
are  established  at  levels  below  the  full  list  price  'of  the  article,  so  that 
the  prices  charged  by  different  retail  stores  will  vary  substantially. 
Moreover,  the  determination  of  the  gross  margins  received  by  dis- 
tributors in  the  drug  trade  is  complicated  by  the  many  special  forms 
of  allowances  which  are  granted  to  stimulate  qu.antity  buying.  In 
addition  to  the  regular  quantity  discount,  so-called  "deals"  are  avail- 
able continuously  or  at  intervals  for  a  wide  range  of  products.  These 
deals  involve  delivering  varying  amounts  of  free  goods  for  purchases 
of  a  specified  amount.  These  free  goods  may  or  may  not  be  of  the 
same  kind  as  those  involved  in  the  purchase;  often  they  are  supple- 
mentary articles.  For  example,  it  is  common  to  use  toothpaste  as  a 
free  deal  in  connection  with  the  sales  of  toothbrushes,  razor  blades 
with  razors,  etc. 

In  general,  free  goods  are  made  available  to  the  retailer  directly  by 
the  manufacturer,  so  that  while  they  mean  a  saving  to  the  retailer, 
they  do  not  imply  any  reduction  in  the  margin  of  the  wholesaler. 

Price  reductions  may  also  take  the  form  of  advertising  allowances 
in  which  the  manufacturer  recompenses  the  dealer  who  advertises  his 
product  either  by  allotting  display  space,  by  advertising  in  local  news- 
papers, or  through  other  means.  Prior  to  the  Robinson-Patman  Act 
these  advertising  allowances  were  often  merely  disguised  means  of 
granting  special  price  concessions  to  large  buyers.  At  present  the  law 
prohibits  this  practice;  the  allowance  must  represent  a  recompense 
for  services  actually  rendered  and  must  also  be  available  on  propor- 
tionately equal  terms  to  all  buyers.  As  a  result,  while  allowances  for 
store  display  are  still  essentially  equivalent  to  price  reductions,  this 
is  not  generally  true  of  allowances  to  compensate  the  retaUer  for 
advertising  placed  in  local  newspapers. 

•  National  Druggists  Association,  Statistical  Division,  Bulletin  No.  12,  June  1930. 

»  U.  S.  Deoartment  of  Commerce,  Census  of  Business:  1935,  "Wholesale  Distribution,"  vol.  I,  p.  57. 


3§§  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

WHOLESALE    AND    RETAIL    MARGINS 

The  range  oj  margins. — In  calculating  distributive  margins  for  par- 
ticular products  it  is  necessary  to  take  all  these  terms  into  account. 
It  is  evident  that  there  will  be  no  single  wholesale  or  retail  margin  for 
most  products,  but  a  range  of  margins.  Since  most  wholesalers  buy- 
in  large  enough  quantities  to  take  advantage  of  all  regular  quantity 
and  cash  discounts  the  prices  they  pay  for  any  article  will  be  fairly 
uniform.  However,  the  mark-ups  which  they  realize  may  vary  ma- 
teriall}'-  on  different  sales,  since  some  of  their  customers  will  be  in  a 
position  to  buy  in  substantial  quantities  and  for  cash  and  thus  to  take 
advantage  of  all  available  discounts,  while  others — often  the  ma- 
jority— can  buy  only  from  hand  to  mouth  and  must  pa}?-  substantially 
more.  The  wholesaler's  mark-up  will  obviously  be  wider  on  the  latter 
than  on  the  former  transaction.  It  should  not  be  inferred,  of  course, 
that  his  net  profit  will  vary  correspondingly,  since  the  higher  price 
paid  by  the  small  retailer  may  less  than  cover  the  added  cost  of  serving 
him. 

As  between  retailers,  the  situation  is  even  more  complex.  It  was 
shown  in  the  preceding  chapter  that  the  independent  retailer,  espe- 
cially the  small  independent,  is  likely  to  charge  the  consumer  some- 
what more  than  the  chain  store,  particularly  for  popular,  nationally 
advertised  merchandise.  At  the  same  time  he  will  usually  also  pay 
more  because  of  his  inability  to  take  full  advantage  of  quantity  and 
cash  discounts,  deals,  and  allowances.  The  large  retailer,  including 
the  chain  store,  ^^^ll  generally  both  pay  less  and  charge  less;  where 
price-maintenance  contracts  have  been  issued  his  selling  price  is  usually 
the  minimum  allowed.  Retailers  who  can  buy  directly  from  the 
manufacturer  can  purchase  many  products  even  more  cheaply  than 
those  who  buy  in  similar  quantities  through  wholesalers.  The  policy 
of  the  manufacturer  is  important  in  this  regard,  some  seek  to  encour- 
age direct  buying,  others  discourage  it,  a  few  will  sell  only  to  whole- 
salers and  refuse  any  form  of  direct  dealing.  Differences  in  the  prices 
paid  by  retailers  for  merchandise  are  probably  narrower  today  than 
they  were  a  few  years  ago,  partly  because  of  the  Robinson-Patman 
Act  which  limits  the  extent  to  which  manufacturers  and  wholesalers 
may  discriminate  in  price  among  their  customers,  and  partly  because 
of  the  advent  of  resale-price  maintenance. 

In  order  to  obtain  information  regarding  the  margins  actually 
prevailing,  a  field  survey  of  a  number  of  representative  manufacturers 
and  wholesalers  was  conducted  during  November  1939.  The  results 
of  this  survey,  which  are  summarized  below,  illustrate  the  varietj'  of 
practices  encountered.  Except  as  otherwise  stipulated,  the  data  in 
each  case  relate  to  conditions  as  of  November  1939. 

Pharmacevtical  "A". — The  dealer's  list  price  (distinct  from  the 
consumer's  list)  for  a  nationally  advertised  pharmaceutical  is  $14.40 
per  gross,  or  10  cents  per  unit.  The  wholesaler  receives  a  15  percent 
trade  and  1  percent  cash  discount  which  brings  his  price  down  to 
8.4  cents.  Price  maintenance  contracts  stipulate  the  wholesaler's 
maximum  discounts  to  retailers  on  the  following  basis: 

Percent 
Purchase  of —  discount 

Under  $2 _  ...  2 

$2to$5.99._ 5 

$6  to  .$15.99 7H 

$16  to  $43.19 10 

$43.20  and  oyer no  stipulation 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


389 


On  this  basis  the  retailer's  purchase  price  and  the  wholesaler's  gross 
margin  *  will  be: 


Retailer's  order 


Retailer's 

Whole- 

purchase 

saler's 

price  (per 

gross 

gross) 

margin 

Percent 

$14. 11 

14.1 

13.68 

11.4 

13.32 

9.0 

12.96 

6.5 

Under  $2  00-... 
$2.00  to  $5.99... 
$6.00  to  $15.99.. 
$16.00  to  $43.19 


This  means  that  the  wholesaler's  gross  margm  on  sales  of  this 
product  will  vary  from  14.1  percent  to  6.5  percent,  depending  upon 
the  quantity  sold;  on  large  orders  it  may  even  be  considerably  less 
than  6  percent. 

In  the  first  place,  large  retailers  may  purchase  direct  from  the  manu- 
facturer if  they  buy  in  quantities  exceeding  $43.19  and  can  show  a 
satisfactory  credit  standing.  The  direct  retail  account  receives  the 
same  discounts  as  the  wholesaler;  that  is,  15  percent  off  list  and  1 
percent  off  net  for  cash. 

In  addition,  there  are  various  free  deals  and  display  allowances 
available  to  retailers  purchasing  through  wholesalers  which  are 
equivalent  to  a  substantial  reduction  in  price.  These  deals  arc  made 
available  by  the  manufacturer  and  do  not  affect  the  wholesaler's 
margin.  The  deals  are  granted  at  the  rate  of  6  percent  of  the  retailer's 
total  purchase  from  the  manufacturer's  representative,  payable  in 
free  goods.  Advertising  allowances  to  wholesaler's  customers  are 
based  on  5  percent  of  the  retailer's  total  purchase,  also  in  free  goods, 
and  are  granted  on  orders  of  $6  and  over.  Direct  buyers  can  obtain 
a  discount  of  5  percent  of  their  annual  net  purchases  if  they  display  the 
product  on  a  basis  stipulated  by  contract. 

By  taking  advantage  of  all  these  allowances,  the  purchaser  of  a 
$10  order  thi'ough  a  wholesaler  can  obtain  111  units  for  a  net  cost 
of  $9.25,  equivalent  to  a  cost  per  unit  of  8.33  cents.  On  a  $16  order 
the  cost  per  unit  will  be  reduced  to  8.11  cents.  The  direct  buyer 
taking  advantage  of  the  display  allowances  will  pay  only  7.99  cents. 

This  product  sells  at  retail  between  12  cents  and  15  cents,  the  former 
being  the  fair-trade  minimum  and  the  latter  the  full  retail  list  price. 
The  gross  margin  to  the  retailer  will  varj ,  depending  both  upon  the 
price  charged  and  upon  his  methods  and  quantities  of  purchase.  To 
the  very  small  buyer  who  pays  9.8  cents  for  each  unit,  the  minimum 
resale  price  of  12  cents  will  allow  only  an  18.3  percent  margin,  while  the 
full  retail  price  of  15  cents  means  a  34.7  percent  margin.  To  the 
retailer  who  buys  in  $16  quantiti(^s,  on  the  other  hand,  even  the  mini- 
mum price  will  allow  a  32.4  percent  gross  margin,  while  the  full  retail 
price  is  equivalent  to  a  45.9  percent  margin.  For  the  direct  buyer  who 
takes  advantage  of  the  display  allowance  even  the  minimum  con- 
sumer's price  affords  a  33.4  percent  gross  margin,  while  the  full  retail 
price  means  a  46.7  percent  margin. 

It  is  obvious  that  no  generalization  with  regard  to  distributive 
margins  for  this  product  is  possible  or  significant.  The  very  small 
retailer,  who  usually  sells  at  the  full  list  price,  will  in  fact  obtain  a 

*  Margins  are  computed  as  percentages  of  the  selling  price  in  each  case.    This  is  the  customary  practice. 


OQQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  EX:;ONOMIC  POWER 

gross  margin  slightly  larger  tlia,n  the  chain  store  which  buys  directly 
and  sells  at  the  fair-trade  minimiun. 

Table  34  summarizes  wholesale  and  retail  margins  under  various 
conditions  of  purchase  and  sale. 

Table  34 — Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationally  advertised  pharmaceutical 

"A" 

Manufacturer's  price  to  wholesalers per  gross.  -  $14.  40 

Manufacturer's   price    to    wholesalers,    less    discounts    (including 

cash) per  gross..  $12.  12 

Net  cost  to  retailers  purchasing  through  wholesalers do $12.  96-14.  11 

Wholesaler's  mark-up percent..  6.  5-14.  1 

Wholesaler's  price  to  retailers,  with  minimuDQ  discount,  and  ex- 
clusive of  free  deals  and  display  allowances per  gross..  $14.  11 

Full  retail  list  price..- each..  $0.  15 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  price percent.  _  34.  7 

Minimum  retail  price each..  $0.  12 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price percent.  _  18.  3 

Wholesaler's  price  to  retailers,  with  maximum  discount,  and  ex- 
clusive of  free  deals  and  display  allowances per  gross..  $12.  96 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price ..percent..  40.  0 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price do 25.  0 

Net  cost  to  retailers  buying  through  wholesalers,  with  maximum 
trade  discount,  with  free  deals  and  display  allowance  (on  $16 

order) per  gross.  .  $1 1.  68 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price percent.  .  45.  9 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price do 32.  4 

Manufacturer's  list  to  direct  customers per  gross. .  $14.  40 

Manufacturer's  price  to  direct  customers,  less  trade  and  cash  dis- 
counts  per  gross..  $12.  12 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price percent. .  43.  9 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price. do 29.  9 

Net  cost  to  direct  customers,  less  trade  and  cash  discounts  and 

display  allowances per  gross...  $11.  51 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price percent.  .  46.  7 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price do 33.  4 

Pharmaceutical  "B." — Another  nationally  advertised  pharmaceuti- 
cal is  sold  outright  to  jobbers.  The  manufacturer's  hst  price  is  $4  per 
dozen  or  33.3  cents  per  unit,  and  all  prices  are  on  a  delivered  basis. 
The  company  has  no  manufacturer-jobber  price  maintenance  con- 
tracts. Jobbers,  who  must  order  in 'quantities  of  at  least  $40,  receive 
a  15  percent  trade  discount  and  a  2  percent  tash  discount,  which 
reduces  their  cost  per  dozen  to  $3.33,  and  unit  cost  to  27.8  cents.  TJie 
jobber  may  grant  dealers  any  discount  he  cares  to  make.  The  manu- 
facturer reports  that  these  range  ordinarily  from  5  to  10  percent, 
depending  upon  competition.  On  this  basis,  the  jobber's  gross  margin 
varies  from  12.4  percent  to  7.5  percent. 

To  the  dealers  purchasing  through  jobbers,  free  deals  and  display 
allowances  which  result  in  a  substantial  decrease  in  the  dealer's  costs 
are  available  on  orders  ranging  from  $6  to  $21.  As  free  deals,  addi- 
tional quantities  of  the  same  product  are  offered;  these  are  given  at 
the  rate  of  one  unit  for  each  $6  order.  Display  allowances  are  granted 
in  the  form  of  free  goods  of  a  somewhat  different  article  and  the  value 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  391 

of  these  allowances  varies  according  to  the  quantity  of  the  order  and 
the  duration  of  the  display.  By  taking  advantage  of  the  free  deals, 
the  purchaser  of  a  $6  order  can  obtain  19  units  for  a  net  cost  of  $5.40 
to  $5.70,  depending  on  the  discount  granted  by  the  jobber,  with  a 
resulting  cost  per  dozen  from  $3.41  to  $3.60  and  a  unit  cost  from 
28.4  cents  to  30  cents.  Sufficient  price  data  are  not  available  to  make 
an  estimate  of  the  value  of  display  allowances  to  these  buyers.  If 
such  a  purchaser  does  not  take  advantage  of  these  free  deals,  his 
unit  cost  varies  from  30  cents  to  31.7  cents,  again  depending  on  the 
jobber's  discount. 

Large  retailors,  whose  minimum  order  must  be  $40  list,  receive  the 
same  discounts  as  do  jobbers;  that  is,  a  15-percent  trade  discount  from 
list  and  a  2-percent  cash  discount  from  net.  These  purchasers  are 
granted  no  free  deals,  but  display  allowances  up  to  5  percent  are  given 
provided  the  retailer  displays  the  merchandise  in  a  manner  acceptable 
to  the  manufacturer.  Taking  into  consideration  the  cash  and  trade 
discounts,  but  not  the  display  allowance,  cost  per  dozen  is  reduced  to 
$3.33  or  27.8  cents  per  unit. 

The  manufacturer  has  established  manufacturer-retailer  contracts 
in  only  one  State;  in  that  State  the  minimum  retail  price  is  set  at  39 
cents.  The  full  list  price  is  50  cents.  The  51  retail  prices  on  this 
product  reported  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  as  of  March  15, 
1939  (including  3  quotations  for  the  State  in  which  minimum  prices  are 
in  force),  ranged  from  29  cen^s  to  50  cents.  Thirty-one  of  these 
quotations  were  from  independent  stores  and  20  from  chain  stores. 
The  range  of  prices  reported  from  chain  stores  was  from  29  cents  to 
39  cents,  with  34  cents  the  modal  price;  the  range  in  independent  stores 
was  29  cents  to  50  cents,  with  39  cents  as  the  modal  price.  For  an 
independent  store  which  purchases  this  product  through  a  jobber,  and 
takes  advantage  of  the  free  deals,  the  modal  price  of  39  cents  affords 
a  gross  margin  of  23.1  percent  to  27.1  percent,  depending  upon  the 
discount  granted  by  the  jobber.  On  this  same  basis  the  full  retail 
price  of  50  cents  afford  margins  ranging  from  40  percent  to  43.2 
percent.  For  a  chain  store  which  buys  dire  tly,  and  takes  advantage 
of  the  cash  discount  but  not  the  display  allo»/ance,  the  modal  price  of 
34  cents  affords  a  margin  of  18.4  percent  and  the  highest  retaU  price 
reported  by  any  chain,  39  cents,  means  a  margin  of  28.8  percent. 

It  is  obvious  that  the  dirept  buyer  of  this  product  does  not  receive 
price  concessions  from  the  manufacturer  great  enough  to  account 
fully  for  the  lower  price  at  which  he  sells  the  product,  and  the  average 
small  retailer  apparently  obtains  a  larger  mark-up  than  does  the 
chain  store.  The  considerably  lower  modal  price  charged  for  this 
product  in  chain  stores  is  probably  due  to  the  fact  that  it  is  very 
commonly  used  as  a  price  leader. 

Table  35  summarizes  retail  and  wholesale  margins  for  this  phar- 
maceutical. For  the  reasons  mentioned  above,  no  account  has  been 
taken  of  the  value  of  display  allowances  to  retailers  purchasing  through 
jobbers.  Since  these  allowances  represent  an  appreciable  reduction  of 
the  net  price' to  these  retailers,  the  margins  shown  in  the  table  should 
be  interpreted  accordingly. 


247149— 41— No.  1 27 


392  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  35. — Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationally  advertised  pharmaceutical 

"B" 

Manufacturer's  list  price dozen. .  $4.  00 

Net  cost  to  jobbers — list,  less  16  percent  trade,  less  2  percent  cash,  .do 3.  33- 

Netcosttoretailerspurchasingthrough jobber8(5percentofif  list)--do 3.  80- 

Jobber's  gross  margin percent.  _     12.  4 

Net  cost  to  retailers  purchasing  through  jobbers  (10  percent  ofif  list) 

dozen.-  $3.  60 
Jobber's  gross  margin percent..       7.  ^ 

Net  cost  to  retailers  purchasing  through  jobbers,  list  less"5  percent,  exclu- 
sive of  free  deals dozen..  $3.  80' 

Net  cost  to  retailers  purchasing  through  jobbers,  list  less  6  percent,  with 

free  deals dozen..  3.  60 

FuU  retail  list  price. each..  .  50 

Retailer's  mark-up,  exclusive  of  free  deals percent.  .  36.  7 

Retailer's  mark-up,  with  free  deals do 40.  0= 

Minimum  retail  price,  where  prescribed each..  $0.  39 

Retailer's  mark-up,  exclusive  of  free  deals percent. .  18.  8 

Retailer's  mark'-up,  with  free  deals do 23.  1 

Net  cost  to  retailers  purchasing  through  jobbers,  list  less  10  percent,  exclu- 
sive of  free  deals dozen.  _  $3.  60 

Net  cost  to  retailers  purchasing  through  jobbers,  list  less  10  percent,  with 

free  deals dozen..  3.  41 

Full  retail  list  price each. .  .  50- 

Retailer's  mark-up,  exclusive  of  free  deals percent. .  40.  0 

Retailer's  mark-up,  with  free  deals do 43.  2" 

Minimum  retaQ  price,  where  prescribed each..  $0.  39 

Retailer's  mark-up,  exclusive  of  free  deals percent. .  23.  1 

Retailer's  mark-up,  with  free  deals do 27.  1 

Manufacturer's  list  to  direct  customers,  less  15  percent  trade,  less  2  per- 
cent cash ,  exclusive  of  display  allowances dozen..  $3.  33 

With  display  allowances do 3.  16 

Full  retail  list  price .  —  . each..       .  50 

Retailer's  mark-up,  exclusive  of  display  allowance percent.  _     44.  5 

Retailer's  mark-up,  with  display  allowance do 47.  3- 

Minimum  retail  price,  where  prescribed each  _  .  $0.  39 

Retailer's  mark-up,  exclusive  of  display  allowance percent..     28.  8 

Retailer's  mark-up,  with  display  allowance do 32.  5 

Modal  price,  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  data  for  chain  stores. .each..  $0.  34 

Retailer's  mark-up,  exclusive  of  display  allowance percent.  _     18.  4 

Retailer's  mark-up,  with  display  allowance do 22.  5 

Lowest  price  reported  to  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  for  chain  stores 

each. .  $0.  29' 

Retailer's  mark-up,  exclusive  of  display  allowance .  .  .percent.  .       4  3 

Retailer's  mark-up,  with  display  allowance do 9.  2 

Drug  sundry. — A  widely  advertised  drug  sundry  affords  an  illus- 
tration of  the  factorship  principle.  The  wholesaler  acts  to  all  intents 
and  purposes  as  the  manufacturer's  agent  and  receives  a  specified 
commission  on  all  sales.  In  addition,  a  bonus  is  paid  to  the  whole- 
saler for  handling  a  designated  quota  of  merchandise.  Direct  sales 
to  retailers  are  made  only  in  single  shipments  amounting  to  at  least 
100  pounds  of  the  two  major  products  of  this  company,  and  it  is  also 
required  that  the  net  purchases  of  such  retailers  be  not  less  than  $500 
each  6  mcmths. 

At  the  present  time  the  factor's  conmiiSsion,  including  his  bonus,, 
ranges  from  17  percent  for  sales  in  lots  of  a  dozen  packages  to  15.4 
percent  for  sales  in  lots  of  one  gross.  These  commissions  have  varied 
only  fractionally  since  1935.  It  is  evident  that  the  gross  margin  to 
the  wholesaler  on  this  item  is  fairly  uniform,  regardless  of  the  size 
of  the  sale.     The  prices  paid  by  retailers  are  also -little  affected  by  the- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


393 


quantity  of  purchase.  At  the  present  time,  for  example,  the  price  pn 
dozen  lots  on  sales  through  factors  is  $2.06  per  dozen  less  10  percent, 
while  on  gross  lots  the  price  per  dozen  is  $2.02  less  10  percent,  repre- 
senting a  quantity  discount  of  only  about  2  percent.  Direct  buyers 
are  granted  a  slight  advantage,  paying  $2.02  less  14%  percent,  less 
1  percent  off  net  for  cash.  In  other  words,  the  smaller  retailer  buying 
in  dozen  lots  pays  15.4  cents  per  imit  while  the  large  direct  buyer 
I>ays  14.25  cents,  representing  a  total  advantage  to  the  large  customer 
of  only  about  7.5  percent.  At  the  retail  price  of  20  cents,  which  is 
the  price  usually  charged  by  both  chain  and  independent  outlets,  this 
is  equivalent  to  a  gross  margin  varying  from  22.9  to  28.8  percent. 

Since  1935  there  have  been  a  number  of  changes  in  both  the  whole- 
sale and  retail  price  structure  of  this  product.  The  price  to  con- 
sumers was  advanced  twice  during  this  period.  The  wholesale  price 
to  direct  buyers  was  also  advanced  but  not  in  the  same  proportion. 
On  the  other  hand,  the  price  paid  by  small  retailers  was  actually  re- 
duced. As  a  result,  the  gross  margin  received  by  the  small  retailer 
on  sales  of  this  product  more  than  doubled,  while  the  margin  of  direct 
buyers  increased  slightly.  Changes  in  factor's  commissions  and 
retailer's  gross  margins  for  this  sundry  are  summarized  in  table  3C 
below.  Retail  margins  are  computed  on  the  basis  of  the  minimum 
fair  trade  price  which  is  also  the  price  most  frequently  charged  by 
both  chain  and  independent  drug  stores. 

Table  36. —  Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationally  advertised  drug  sundry 


Aug.  15,  1935, 

through  June 

28,  1936 

June  29, 1936, 

through  Jan. 

1,  1937 

Jan.  2.  1937, 

through  Apr. 
30,  1937 

May  1, 1937, 

through  Dec. 

31,  1938 

Jan.  1, 1939, 

through  Nov. 

16,  1939 

Manufacturer's  commission 
to  factors,  percent 

14.0-17.1 

14. 1-17. 1 

15.4-17.0 

15.4-17.1 

16. 4-17. 0 

Manufacturer's  list  to  fac- 
tor's customers,  per  dozen. 

Manufacturer's  list  to  fac- 
tor's customers,  less  trade 
discount,  per  dozen 

$1. 87-$l.  94 

$1.87-$1.94 

$1. 78-$l.  88 
$0.19 

17. 5-21.  9 

$1.  90-$l.  94 

$1. 81-$1. 88 
$0.19 

17. 5-20. 6 

$2. 02-$2.  06 

$1.32-$1.85 
$0.20 

22.9-24.2 

$2.02-$2.06 
$1. 82-$l.  85 

Usual  retail  price,  each 

Gross   mark-up   to   factor's 
customers,  percent 

$0.18 
10. 2-13. 4 

$0.20 
22.  *-24.  2 

Manufacturer's  list  to  direct 
buyers,  per  dozen 

$1.  84-$l.  92 

$1.64-$1.71 
$0.18 

20. 8-24. 1 

$1.59 
26.4 

$1. 87-$l.  92 

$1. 67-$l.  71 
$0.19 

25. 0-26.  8 

$1.62 
28.9 

$1.  92-$2.  02 

$1.  70-$l.  72 
$0.19 

24. 6-25.  4 

$1.63 
28.5 

$2.02-$2.04 

$1.  71-$1.  73 
$0.20 

27. 9-28. 8 

$2.02 

Less    trade    discount,    less 
cash  discount,  per      zen... 

Usual  retail  price,  each 

Gross  mark-up  to  direct  buy- 
ers, percent 

$1.71 
$0.20 

28.8 

Less   trade   discount,   cash 
discount  and  carload  quan- 
tity discount,  per  dozen 

Gross  mark-up  to  direct  buy- 
ers, percent. 

Toiletry  "A". — A  nationally  advertised  toiletry  is  also  sold  on 
the  factorship  basis.  The  wholesaler's  list  price  is  $3.20  per  dozen, 
or  26.7  cents  per  unit.  The  factor  receives  a  15  percent  commission 
from  this  list,  less  2  percent  of  net  for  cash  received  within  10  days  of 
invoice.  In  addition,  a  bonus  of  5  percent  from  net  (before  the  2 
percent  is  deducted)  is  given  for  satisfactory  performance  in  accord- 
ance with  the  factorship  agreement.  If  all  these  discounts  are 
received,  they  bring  the  factor's  price  down  to  21.1  cents  per  unit. 


394  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Retailers  purchasing  through  factors  are  granted  the  following 
discounts: 

Quantity  purchased:  Peremt  ditcount 

Less  than  6  units 3 

6  units 8 

$24.00  order  or  more  of  any  of  manufacturer's  products 10 

On  this  basis  the  retailer's  purchase  price  may  vary  from  25.8  cents 
per  unit  to  24  cents.  The  factor's  gross  margin,  including  his  bonus, 
can  vary  from  18.4  percent  to  12.2  percent,  depending  upon  the 
quantity  purchased  by  the  retailer. 

Retailers  purchasing  a  minimum  of  $100  of  any  of  this  manufac- 
turer's products  in  a  single  shipment  may  purchase  direct  from  the 
manufacturer.  On  such  purchases,  the  retailer  is  allowed  a  deduction 
of  15  percent  from  list,  less  2  percent  from  net  for  cash  received 
within  10  days  of  invoice. 

The  dealer  purchasing  through  a  wholesale  factor  has  a  unit  cost 
of  24  cents  to  25.8  cents,  depending  on  whether  he  purchases  less  than 
one-half  dozen  units,  or  as  much  as  $24.  Direct  purchasers  obtain 
their  goods  at  a  cost  of  $2.67  per  dozen  and  a  unit  cost  of  22.3  cents. 
Advertising  allowances  amounting  to  5  percent  of  net  purchases 
for  the  previous  6-month  period  are  available  to  all  retailers  on  a 
contractual  basis  to  compensate  for  the  actual  cost  of  the  advertise- 
ments inserted.  The  advertisements  must  appear  in  established  daily 
newspapers  and  tear  sheets  must  be  submitted  as  evidence.  No  deals 
were  ofifered  during  1939. 

ThiSj  product  sells  at  retail  between  33  cents  and  40  cents,  the 
former  being  the  fair-trade  minimum  and  the  latter  the  full  list  price. 
Of  the  20  quotations  reported  to  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  on 
this  product  as  of  June  1939,  18  were  at  33  cents,  1  at  36  cents,  and 
1  at  39  cents.     However,  data  supplied  by  the  manufacturers  indicate 
that  the  average  retail  price  during  the  period  1937-40  has  been 
about  36  cents.     The  retailer's  gross  margin  depends,  therefore,  upon 
the  retail  price  he  charges  and  the  quantity  he  purchases  at  a  given 
time.     To  the  retailer  whose  unit  cost  is  25.8  cents,  the  minimum 
resale  price  of  33  cents  allows  a  21.7  percent  margin,  while  the  full 
list  price  of  40  cents  aUows  a  35.4  percent  margin.     To  the  retailer 
who  buys  the  manufacturers'  products  through  a  factor  in  $24  lots, 
the  minimum  retail  price  affords  a  margin  of  27.3  percent,  and  the 
full  list  a  margin  of  40  percent.     The  minimum  price  allows  the  direct 
buyer  a  gross  margin  of  32.6  percent  and  the  full  hst,  44.4  percent. 
"The  retailer  receiving  the  minimum  discounts  and  selling  at  full 
list  obtains  a  slightly  higher  gross  margin  than  does  the  large  pur- 
chaser who  receives   the  maximum  allowances   and  resells   at   the 
minimum. 

These  data  are  summarized  in  table  37. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         395 

Table  37. — Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationally  advertised  toiletry  "A" 

Manufacturer's  list  price dozen. .  $3.  20 

To  wholesale-factors,  list,  less  15  percent  trade,  less  2  percent  cash,  less 

5  percent  bonus dozen..  $2.  53 

To  retailers  purchasing  less  than  3^  dozen — Ust,  less  3  percent-do $3.  10 

Wholesaler's  mark-up percent..     18.  4 

To  retailers  purchasing  %  dozen  to  $24  assorted  order — list,  less  8 

percent dozen  _ .  $2.  94 

Wholesaler's  mark-up percent..     13.  9 

To  retailers  purchasing  $24  order  of  manufacturer's  products — list, 

10  percent dozen..  $2.  88 

Wholesaler's  mark-up percent..     12.  2 

To  retailers  purchasing  through  wholesale-factor — list,  less  3  per- 
cent  dozen.  _  $3.  10 

Full  retail  list  price each.  _  $0.  40 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price percent..     35.  4 

Minimum  retail  price each.  .  $0.  33 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price percent.  _     21.  7 

To   retailers  purchasing  through  wholesale-factor — list,  less   8  per- 
cent  dozen. .   $2.  94 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price. _•. percent..     38.  8 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price do 25.  8 

To  retailers  purchasing  through  wholesale-factor — list,  less  10  per- 
cent  dozen.  _  $2.  88 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  list  retail  price percent. .     40.  0 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price do 27.  3 

To  retailers  purchasing  from  manufacturer — list,  less  15  percent,  less  2 

percent dozen .  .  $2.  67 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price percent.  .     44.  4 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price do 32.  6 

Toiletry  "B". — The  manufacturer  of  another  nationally  advertised 
toiletry  maintains  his  own  sales  organization  for  supplying  retailers, 
and  by  far  the  larger  volume  of  sales  is  made  direct.  This  product  is 
offered  in  three  package  sizes;  small,  intermediate,  and  large.  Of 
these,  the  small  accounts  for  the  largest  number  of  unit  sales.  The 
list  price  to  jobbers  for  the  small  size  is  75  cents  per  dozen,  or  6.25 
cents  per  unit.  No  trade  discount  is  given,  but  a  2  percent  cash 
discount  is  available  which  reduces  the  retailer's  cost  to  73.5  cents  per 
dozen.  The  manufacturer  has  no  contracts  with  jobbers  stipulating 
the  price  they  must  charge  the  retailer,  but  the  manufacturer  "sug- 
gests" a  price  of  85  cents  per  dozen  which  affords  a  13.5  percent  gross 
margin  to  the  jobber. 

Several  possibilities  as  to  methods  of  purchase  are  available  to  the 
retailer.  Retailers  buying  direct  pay  75  cents  per  dozen,  and  are 
allowed  a  2-percent  discount  for  cash  received  within  10  days  of 
delivery. 

The  suggested  price  to  retailers  buying  from  jobbers  or  wholesalers 
is  85  cents  per  dozen,  or  7.1  cents  per  unit.  No  free  deals  are  offered 
on  this  product.  The  minimum  retail  price  is  10  cents,  which  is  also 
the  full  retail  price.  Assuming  a  retailer  buys  through  a  jobber  and 
thus  pays  85  cents  per  dozen,  this  price  affords  him,  a  margin  of  29.2 
percent;  for  a  retailer  purchasing  direct  and  taking  advantage  of  the 
cash  discount  affords  a  margin  of  38.8  percent. 

On  the  two  larger  sizes  the  jobber's  margin  is  15.1  percent  and  14.4 
percent  respectively  as  compared  with  his  13.5  percent  margin  on  the 
small  size.  In  contrast,  retailers  obtain  a  much  smaller  margin  on 
the  larger  sizes  which  they  sell  at  the  minimum  retail  price,  although 


396         CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

the  large  size  affords  a  greater  margin  than  does  the  intermediate  size. 
Direct  buyers  obtain  a  margin  of  27.3  percent  and  30.8  percent  on  the 
larger  sizes  as  compared  with  38.8  percent  on  the  small  size;  indirect 
buyers  receive  a  margin  of  14.4  percent  and  19.2  percent  on  the  larger 
sizes,  29.2  percent  on  the  small  size.  If  the  full  list  price  is  charged 
for  the  two  larger  sizes,  the  direct  buyer  obtains  a  margin  of  31.1 
percent  and  34.8  percent,  as  contrasted  with  the  18.9  percent  and  23.8 
percent  obtained  by  the  indirect  buyer. 

No  advertising  allowances  are  available  on  the  small  size,  but  they 
are  granted  on  the  two  larger  sizes  as  reimbursement  for  actual  expen- 
ditures made  for  advertising.  The  amount  of  these  allowances  is 
varied  from  time  to  time,  but  they  are  usually  5  percent  of  net  sales 
for  a  3  months  period. 

These  data  are  summarized  in  table  38. 


Table  38. —  Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationally  advertised  toiletry  "B" 


Small 
size 


Tntermedi' 
ate  size 


Large 
size 


Manufacturer's  list  to  jobbers - dozen. 

Manufacturer's  list  to  jobbers,  less  cash  discount -- do... 

"Suggested"  price  to  jobbers'  customers - do.-. 

Jobber's  mark-up.  _- - . percent  - 

"Suggested"  price  to  retailers dozen. 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price .percent- 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  price.- ---- do... 

Manufacturer's  list  to  direct  buyer.. dozen. 

Less  cash  discount do... 

Full  retail  list  price ^ each. 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price .per<jent. 

Minimum  retail  sale  price each. 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  price ...percent. 


$0.75 

.735 

.85 

13.5 


$1.60 
1.57 
1.86 
15.1 


$2.80 
2.74 
3.20 
14.4 


$.85 
29.2 
29.2 


$.75 
.735 
.10 
38.8 
$.10 
38.8 


$1.85 
22.9 
14.4 


$1.60 
1.57 
.20 
34.6 
$.18 
27.3 


$3.20 
23.8 
19.2 

$2.80 
2.74 
.35 
34.8 
$.33 
30.8 


Toiletry  "C" — This  product  is  sold  either  through  wholesalers  or 
directly  to  retailers.  Orders  from  wholesalers,  as  well  as  direct  sales 
must  be  in  minimum  quantities  of  $48,  but  may  include  any  com- 
bination of  the  manufacturer's  products.  Minimum  resale  prices  for 
both  wholesalers  and  retailers  are  set  by  contract. 

The  list  price  to  wholesalers  or  jobbers  is  $2  per  dozen.  They 
receive  a  trade  discount  of  15  percent  and  a  cash  discount  of  2  per- 
cent, which  reduces  the  price  per  dozen  to  $1.67,  and  per  unit  to  13.9 
cents.  The  manufacturer-wholesaler  price  maintenance  contracts 
stipulate  a  1  percent  cash  discount  to  indirect  buyers  on  orders  of 
less  than  $2,  and  a  5  percent  discount  inclusive  of  cash  for  orders  of 
$2  or  more.  On  this  basis  the  indirect  buyer's  cost  varies  from  $1.90 
to  $1.98  per  dozen,  and  the  wholesaler's  gross  margin  varies  from  12.1 
percent  to  15.7  percent,  depending  upon  the  size  of  the  order. 

Direct  customers  receive  the  same  discounts  as  wholesalers  and 
jobbers;  that  is,  15  percent  off  list,  less  2  percent  for  cash.  This 
reduces  the  cost  to  $1.67  per  dozen  an"d  13.9  cents  per  unit. 

As  previously  shown,  retailers  purchasing  through  wholesalers  pay 
$1.90  to  $1.98  per  dozen,  depending  upon  the  quantity  purchased  at 
any  one  time.  During  1939^  two  units  of  this  toiletry  were  offered 
with  each  $6  order  (list  prices).  .This  offer  was  available  only  to 
retailers  purchasing  through  wholesalers  or  jobbers.  Considering  the 
value  of  this  deal,  the  unit  cost  is  reduced  to  15  cents.  Deals  involv- 
ing other  of  the  company's  products  were  also  offered  during  1939. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  397 

Some  advertising  allowances  are  made  from  time  to  time,  available 
to  all  retailers,  but  no  detailed  data  regarding  these  have  been  com- 
piled. 

This  product  retails  between  19  cents  and  25  cents.  The  former  is 
the  minimum  allowed  under  resale  price  maintenance  contracts,  the 
latter  is  the  full  list  price.  The  gross  margin  to  the  retailer  varies 
with  the  method  of  pm-chasing  and  the  quantity  of  the  order.  To 
the  small  retailer  who  buys  in  quantities  under  $2,  the  minimum 
retail  price  allows  a  margin  of  13.2  percent,  and  the  full  list  price  a 
mark-up  of  34  percent.  If  his  order  is  from  $2  to  $6,  the  minimum 
retail  price  affords  a  margin  of  16.7  percent,  the  full  list  a  margin 
of  36.7  percent.  In  1939  if  his  order  was  $6  or  more,  he  could  take 
advantage  of  the  "free  deal"  and  receive  38  rather  than  the  custom- 
ary 36  units.  In  this  case  the  minimum  retail  price  yielded  a 
margin  of  21.1  percent,  and  the  full  Ust  a  margin  of  40  percent. 

To  the  large  retailer  who  purchased  directly  from  the  manufacturer 
and  took  advantage  of  the  cash  discount,  the  minimum  retail  price 
afforded  a  26.7  percent  margin,  and  the  full  list  price  44.3  percent. 

In  other  words,  the  large  retailer  normally  obtains  a  10  percent 
larger  mark-up  than  the  small  retailer  when  the  two  sell  at  the  same 
retail  price,  but  this  differential  was  reduced  to  approximately  5 
percent  by  the  "free  deal"  offer  in  1939. 

These  data  are  summarized  in  table  39: 

Table  39. —  Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  Toiletry  "C" 

Manufacturer's  list  price — dozen.  _  $2.  00s 

To  wholesalers  and  jobbers — list,  less  15  percent,  less  2  percent  cash 

discount dozen. _  $1.  67 

To  retailers  buying  through  wholesalers  and  jobbers,  less  1  percent 

for  orders  less  than  $2 dozen.  .  $1.  98 

Less  5  percent  for  orders  of  $2  or  more .do $1.  90 

Wholesalers'  mark-up  on  orders  of  less  than  $2 ...percent..  ^15.  7 

Wholesalers'  mark-up  on  orders  of  $2  and  over do 12.  1 

Net  cost  to  retailers  purchasing  through  wholesalers,  exclusive  of  free 

deals,  on  orders  less  than  $2 dozen..  $1.  98 

Minimum  retail  price .each..     $.  19 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price percent..     13.  2 

Full  retail  list  price i each..     $.  25 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price percent.  .     34.  0 

Net  cost  to  retailers  purchasing  through  wholesalers,  exclusive  of  free 

deals,  on  orders  of  $2  io  $6 - dozen..  $1.  9a 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price percent..     To.  7 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price do 36.  7 

Net  cost  to  retailers  purchasing  through  wholesalers,  on  orders  of  $6 

or  more,  with  free  deals dozen..  $1.80 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price percent..  21.  1 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price , do 40.  0 

Net  cost  to  retailers  purchasing  directly  from  manufacturer — list,  less  15 

percent,  less  2  percent ...dozen..  $1.  67 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price percent.  .     26.  7 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  full  retail  list  price do 44.  3 

Cosmetic.  "^."— The  manufacturer  of  a  nationally  advertised 
cosmetic  employs  the  wholesaler  in  the  capacity  of  a  del  credere 
factor.  The  wholesale  Ust  price  is  $8  per  dozen,  or  66.7  cents  per 
unit.  The  manufacturers  allow  the  factor  a  commission  of  5  percent, 
and  a  cash  discount  of  1  percent  from  net,  plus  an  additional  10 


398         CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

percent  off  net.  This  brings  the  unit  cost  down  to  56.3  cents.  The 
price  to  a  retailer  purchasing  through  a  wholesaler  is  33%  percent 
from  Ust.  The  wholesaler  is  allowed  to  use  his  own  discretion  as  to 
whether  or  not  a  cash  discount  is  granted,  but,  according  to  the 
manufacturer,  the  wholesaler  usually  grants  the  retailer  a  2  percent 
discount.  This  means  that  the  wholesaler's  gross  margin  is  13.8 
percent,  from  which  his  freight  costs  must  be  deducted. 

Retailers  whose  net  purchases  amount  to  $300  per  year,  and  who 
have  a  good  credit  standing,  may  purchase  directly  from  the  manu- 
facturer. The  list  price  to  direct  buyers  is  $12  per  dozen,  less  trade 
discounts  of  33 K  percent  and  5  percent,  and  a  cash  discount  of  1 
percent  from  net.  The  cost  per  dozen  is  thus  reduced  to  $7.52  and 
the  unit  cost  to  62.7  cents.  The  retailer  purchasing  from  the  whole- 
saler is  granted  a  trade  discount  of  33}^  percent,  and  is  usually  allowed 
a  2  percent  cash  discount  by  the  wholesaler.  His  cost  per  dozen  is 
then  $7.84,  and  his  unit  cost  65.3  cents.  No  free  deals  have  been 
granted  on  this  cosmetic. 

The  manufacturer's  resale  price  contracts  fix  the  minimum  retail 
price  at  the  fuU  list  of  $1,  which  is  therefore  the  price  charged  uni- 
versally, at  least  in  fair-trade  States.  This  affords  the  retailer  buying 
through  a  wholesaler  a  mark-up  of  34.7  percent  aUowing  for  a  2 
percent  cash  discount.  The  direct  buyer  obtains  a  gross  margin  of 
37.3  percent. 

Advertising  allowances  are  on  a  cooperative  basis,  with  manufac- 
turer and  retailer  sharing  equally  the  costs  of  advertising  a  combina- 
tion of  manufacturer's  products. 

These  data  are  summarized  in  table  40 : 

Table  40. — Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationally  advertised  Cosmetic  "A" 

Manufacturer's  list  to  wholesalers,  per  dozen $8.  00 

Less  trade  discount  of  5  percent,  less  10  percent,  less  1  percent  cash, 

per  dozen $6.  76 

List  to  retailer,  less  33H  percent  trade  discount,  per  dozen $8.  00 

Wholesaler's  margin,  percent 15.  5 

List  to  retailer,  less  33)4  percent  trade  discount,  less  2  percent  cash, 

per  dozen. . _ $7.  84 

Wholesaler's  mark-up,  percent 13.8 

Manufacturer's  list  to  retailer  purchasing  through  wholesaler,  per  dozen.  $12.  00 
Less  trade  discount  of  33}i  percent,  less  2  percent  for  cash,  per 

dozen $7.  84 

"Minimum"  retail  price,  each $1.00 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price,  percent 34.  7 

Manufacturer's  list  to  retailers  buying  direct,  per  dozen $12.  00 

Less  trade  discounts  of  33)4  percent,  less  5  percent,  less  1  percent 

cash,  per  dozen * $7.  52 

"Minimum"  retail  price,  each $1.  00 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price,  percent 37.  3 

Cosmetic  "-5". — The  manufacturer  of  another  brand  of  cosmetic 
sells  outright  to  jobbers  and  wholesalers,  and  also  to  direct  customers. 
Both  manufacturer-wholesaler  and  manufacturer-retailer  contracts  are 
in  effect. 

The  retail  list  price  is  55  cents  per  unit  or  $6.60  per  dozen.  The 
wholesaler  receives  trade  discounts  of  33  K  percent  off  list,  making  the 
wholesale  Ust  price  $4.40  per  dozen.  The  wholesaler  also  receives  10 
percent  off  this  wholesale  list,  5  percent  off  net  (provided  he  purchases 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER         399 

in  lots  of  $50  or  more)  and  1  percent  off  net  for  cash.  This  reduces 
his  cost  per  dozen  to  $3.72  and  the  unit  cost  to  31  cents.  Price  main- 
tenance contracts  stipulate  the  wholesaler's  price  to  retailers  as  retail 
list,  less  ZS%  percent,  regardless  of  quantity.  The  wholesaler  may, 
at  his  discretion,  allow  an  added  1  percent  off  net  for  cash.  On  this 
basis  the  retailer's  cash  purchase  price  will  be  $4.36,  or  36.3  cents  per 
unit,  and  the  wholesaler's  gross  margin  14.7  percent.  (If  the  retailer 
does  not  receive  the  cash  discount,  the  wholesaler's  margin  will  be 
15.5  percent.) 

Direct  retail  purchasers  receive  33%  percent  discount  off  retail  list, 
less  5  percent  off  net  on  orders  of  $25  or  over,  less  1  percent  cash  dis- 
count. This  reduces  the  cost  per  dozen  to  $4.14  and  unit  cost  to  34.5 
cents. 

The  manufacturer  pays  one-half  the  cost  of  newspaper  advertising, 
up  to  5  percent  of  the  retailer's  annual  net  purchases.  No  free  deals 
are  given. 

The  minimum  retail,  as  well  as  the  list  price  on  this  product,  is  55 
cents  each.  To  the  direct  buyer  who  takes  advantage  of  the  cash  dis- 
count, this  price  affords  a  gross  margin  of  37.3  percent.  The  retailer 
who  purchases  through  wholesalers,  obtains  a  margin  of  33.3  or  33.9 
percent,  depending  upon  whether  a  cash  discount  is  offered  and 
received. 

This  manufacturer  packages  the  same  powder  in  a  larger  container 
than  that  described  above.  The  following  table  shows  that  the  mark- 
ups stipulated  by  the  manufacturer  on  these  two  sizes  are  identical. 

These  data  are  summarized  in  table  41: 

Table  41. — Wholesale  and  retail  margins  for  nationally  advertised  Cosmetic  "B" 

Manufacturer's  retail  list  price,  per  dozen $6.  60 

To  wholesalers  and  jobbers — list,  less  33>^  percent,  less  10  percent,  less 

5  percent,  less  1  percent,  per  dozen $3.  72 

To  retailers  purchasing  through  wholesalers — list,  less  33 J^  percent, 

less  1  percent  cash,  per  dozen $4.  36 

Wholesalers'  and  jobbers'  gross  mark-ups,  percent 14.  7 

To  retailers  purchasing  through  wholesalers — list,  less  33 )i  percent, 

less  1  percent  cash,  per  dozen $4.  36 

Minimum  retail  price,  each $0.  55 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  minimum  retail  price,  percent 33.  9 

To  retailers  purchasing  directly  from  manufacturer — list,  less  SSyi  per- 
cent, less  5  percent,  less  1  percent,  per  dozen $4.  14 

Minimum  retail  price,  each $0.  55 

Retailer's  mark-up  on  "minimum"  retail  price,  percent 37.  3 

Cosmetic  "C". — In  the  case  of  some  products,  deals  and  terms  are 
so  complex  that  it  is  difficult  to  translate  them  into  definite  percentage 
margins.  For  example,  the  manufacturer  of  another  nationally  adver- 
tised cosmetic  also  produces  many  other  related  articles.  Display 
allowances  and  free  deals  are  generally  offered  in  terms  of  combina- 
tions of  several  of  these  products.  In  addition,  price  maintenance 
contracts  have  been  issued  in  five  western  States  only  and  terms  of 
sale  in  these  States  vary  from  those  in  other  parts  of  the  country. 

The  largest  volume  of  sales  is  through  wholesalers,  although  some 
sales  are  made  directly  to  retailers.  Only  chain  stores  with  three  or 
more  units  and  department  stores  can  qualify  for  direct  accounts. 
In  those  States  in  which  price  maintenance  contracts  are  in  effect,  it  is 


400 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


also  specified  that  a  direct  buyer  must  order  either  an  18-dozen 
assortment  or  $40  worth  of  goods  in  each  shipment.  The  manu- 
facturer's price  Hst  is  the  same  in  all  States,  but  discounts  and  deals 
offered  to  wholesalers  and  to  indirect  buyers  in  the  five  States  in  which 
contracts  have  been  issued  are  more  liberal  than  in  *'non  fair  trade" 
States.  However,  while  indirect  buyers  in  "non  fair  trade"  States  do 
not  generally  receive  as  liberal  discounts  as  those  in  "fair  trade" 
States,  the  former  are  granted  display  allowances  and  more  libera]  free- 
deal  terms  than  are  the  latter.  Discoimts  to  direct  buyers  are  the 
same  everywhere.  It  is  not  possible  to  show  comparative  mark-ups 
because  adequate  retail  price  data  in  the  "non  fair  trade"  States  are 
not  available. 

Table  42  summarizes  the  terms  granted  by  the  manufacturer: 

Table  42. —  Terms  of  sale  for  Cosmetic  "C" 


"Non  fair  trade"  States 

"Fair  trade"  States 

Manufacturer's  list  pric6 

$4.65  per  dozen 

$4.65  per  dozen. 

Discounts    to     wholesalers    and 

15  percent  trade,  less  1  percent 

15  percent  trade,  less  10  percent 

jobbers. 

cash. 

trade,  less  1  percent  cash. 

Discounts    to    retailers    buying 

Not    fixed     by    manufacturer— 

Orders  under  $6—10  percent. 

through  wholesalers. 

usually  varies  from  5  to  10  per- 

Orders $6  to  $12— 12J^  percent. 

cent. 

Orders  $12  and  over— 15  percent. 

$2  order— choice  of  1  unit  of  2 

$3  order— choice  of  1  unit  of  2 

other  products. 

other  products. 

Display  allowance  to  retailers  buy- 

5 percent  discount  from  list,  or  free 

None. 

ing  through  wholesalers '. 

goods. 

Discounts  to  direct  account 

15  percent  trade,  less  1  percent 

15  percent  trade,  less  10  percent 

cash;  and  free  goods  or  an  addi- 

trade, less  1  percent  cash. 

tional  10  percent  from  net. 

'  Offered  only  periodically,  and  items  purchased  must  be  in  specified  ratio  to  one  another. 

Summary  for  eight  products. — Margins  for  the  products  described 
(with  the  exception  of  the  last,  for  which  data  are  inadequate)  are 
summarized  in  table  43.  It  is  evident  that,  despite  differences  in 
detail,  practice  is  fairly  consistent.  Margins  to  wholesalers  on  small 
sales,  which  probably  constitute  the  bulk  of  their  business,  average 
about  15  percent  in  all  cases.  Wholesalers'  margins  on  large  sales 
vary,  falling  into  two  groups.  In  the  case  of  the  two  pharmaceuticals, 
and  toiletry  "A,"  they  are  substantially  lower  than  on  small  sales, 
ranging  from  6  to  8  percent.  For  the  drug  sundry,  toiletry  "C"  and 
cosmetic  "A,"  the  wholesaler's  mark-up  is  only  slightly  lower  on  large 
sales  than  on  smaU,  and  for  cosmetic  "B"  and  toiletry  "B"  the 
mark-up  is  the  same  regardless  of  the  size  of  the  transaction.  In 
general,  therefore,  a  15-percent  margin  for  products  of  this  kind  may 
be  considered  the  norm.^ 

Retail  mark-ups  also  fall  into  a  fairly  well-defined  pattern.  Re- 
tailers, particularly  independents,  have  usually  regarded  33%  percent 
of  the  selling  price  as  a  satisfactory  mark-up  and  have  at  times  stated 
this  position  through  their  trade  associations.  This  is  the  desired 
margin  without  any  allowance  for  cash  discounts,  of  which  many  small 
retailers  are  unable  to  take  advantage.  Including  one  or  two  percent 
for  cash,  the  desired  mark-up  would  range  from  about  34  to  36  percent. 

The  table  shows  that  the  mark-up  to  the  small  retailer,  buying  at 
maximum  cost  and  selling  at  the  full  list  price  falls  into  precisely  this 

>  It  is  significant  In  this  connection  that  manufacturers'  discounts  to  wjioiesalers  (exclusive  of  cash)  are 
usually  expressed  as  16  percent  directly  or  as  10  and  5  which  is  equivalent  to  14H  percent. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


401 


range  for  six  of  the  eight  products,  is  slightly  lower  for  toiletry 
"B,"  and  is  significantly  lower  only  in  the  case  of  the  drug  sundry. 
Where  wholesalers  allow— or  are  permitted  to  allow — quantity  dis- 
counts, retailers  who  can  take  advantage  of  these  extra  allowances  can 
obtain  mark-ups  of  about  40  percent  by  selling  at  full  list. 


Table  43. — Wholesale  and  retail  mark- 

ups  for  8  nationally  advertised  products 

Pharma- 
ceutical 
A 

Pharma- 
ceutical 
B 

Toiletry 
A 

Toiletry 
B 

Cosmetic 
A 

Cosmetic 
B 

Toiletry 
C 

Drug 
Sundry 

Margin    to    whole- 

salers: 

Buying  at  mini- 

mum,   selling 

Percent 

Percent 

Percent 

Percent 

Percent 

Percent 

Percent 

Percent 

at  maximum-- 

14.1 

12.4 

18.4 

13.5 

15.6' 

14.7 

15.7 

17.0 

"Buying  at  max  - 

mum,    selling 

at  minimum... 

6.5 

7.5 

12.2 

13.5 

13.6 

14.7 

12.1 

15.4 

Margin  to  retailers 

buying      through 

wholesalers: 

Selling    at    full 

retail  list: 

Buying     at 

minimum.. 

45.9 

43.2 

40.0 

29.2 

34.7 

33.9 

40.0 

24.2 

Buying     at 

maximum. 

34.7 

36.7 

35.4 

29.2 

34.7 

33.9 

34.0 

22.9 

Selling  at  mini- 

mum retail: 

Buying     at 

minimum_ 

32.4 

27.1 

27.3 

29.2 

34.  7 

33.9 

21.1 

24.2 

Buying     at 

maximum. 

18.3 

18.8 

21.7 

29.2 

34.7 

33.9 

13.2 

22.9 

Margin  to  retailers 

buying      directly 

from        manufac- 

turer: 

Selling    at    full 

retail!  ist: 

Buying     at 

minimum.. 
Buymg     at 
maximum. 

46.7 

47.3 

44.4 

38.8 

37.3 

37.3 

44.3 

28.8 

43.9 

44.5 

44.4 

38.8 

37.3 

37.3 

44.3 

28.8 

Selling  at  mini- 

mum retail: 
Buying     at 
minin^um^ 

33.4 

32.5 

32.6 

38.8 

37.3 

37.3 

26.7 

28.8 

Buying     at 

maximum - 

29.9 

28.8 

32.6 

38.8 

37.3 

37.3 

26.7 

28.8 

Source:  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

Contractual  minimum  prices,  on  the  other  hand,  when  these  are 
below  list,  allow  substantially  narrower  margins  to  the  indirect  buying 
retailer.  For  those  who  can  take  advantage  of  full  quantity  discounts 
and  deals,  the  mark-ap  averages  about  25  percent;  for  those  who  buy 
at  maximum  cost,  the  range  wias  from  13  to  23  percent. 

Retailers  buying  direct  from  the  manufacturer  are  generally  able 
to  buy  more  cheaply  than  those  who  buy  through  wholesalers.  The 
full  Ust  price  yields  mark-ups  ranging  as  high  as  47  percent.  However, 
it  is  probable  that  most  direct  buyers  sell  at  or  near  the  minimum 
price,  when  that  is  below  the  list  price,  and  actual  mark-ups  are 
consequently  somewhat  narrower.  For  the  eight  products  shown  the 
range  of  mark-ups  based  upon  the  minimum  price  was  from  27  to  39 
percent,  with  an  average  of  about  33  percent.  In  other  words,  the 
mark-up  of  the  small  retailer,  buying  in  small  quantities  at  maximum 


402         CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

cost  and  usually  selling  at  or  near  the  full  list  price,  is  about  the  same 
as  that  of  the  large  direct  buyer  who  typically  resells  at  the  minimum. 

Margins  allowed  by  a  large  drug  manufacturer. — There  is  evidence 
that  these  conclusions  are  generally  applicable  to  a  fairly  wide  range 
of  products.  For  example,  a  large  drug  manufacturer  prescribes 
terms  of  sale  to  consumers  and  to  retailers  in  detail  and  divides  his 
line  of  merchandise  into  three  groups.  One  of  these  three  groups 
contains  somewhat  over  one  hundred  different  items,  including 
primarily  household  remedies  and  toiletries.  Most  of  these  items  are 
relatively  "fast  selling"  and  are  often  featured  on  a  price  basis.  The 
retailer  who  purchases  an  assortment  of  $10  or  more  of  this  manu- 
facturer's products  is  entitled  to  a  10  percent  quantity  discount  from 
the  price  charged  retailers  who  buy  in  smaller  quantities,  while 
retailers  who  purchase  $25  or  more  on  a  single  order  obtain  a  15  percent 
quantity  discount.  In  addition  a  one  percent  cash  discount  is  also 
offered.  Consequently,  the  retailer  who  purchases  in  large  quantities 
can  obtain  merchandise  at  about  15.9  percent  below  the  cost  to  the 
retailer  who  buys  in  minimum  quantities.  Minimum  prices  have 
been  set  by  contract  for  all  this  range  of  products  and  in  practically 
all  cases  the  minimum  pnce  is  somewhat  below  the  full  list  price. 

The  gross  margins  available  to  retailers  for  each  product  in  this 
group  have  been  computed  under  four  conditions: 

(1)  Purchases  at  maximum  cost  and  resale  at  the  minimum  contract 
price. 

(2)  Purchases  at  minimum  cost  and  resale  at  the  minimum  price. 

(3)  Purchases  at  maximum  cost  and  resale  at  the  full  list  price. 

(4)  Purchases  at  minimum  cost  and  resale  at  the  full  list  price. 
Table  44  indicates  the  number  of  items  under  wliich  specified 

mark-ups  can  be  obtained  under  each  of  these  four  conditions.  It 
is  evident  that  the  gross  margins  for  these  items  fall  into  much  the 
same  pattern  as  that  observed  for  the  more  limited  list  of  products 
which  has  been  described  above.  The  small  retailer  who  buys  in 
minimum  quantities  and  resells  at  the  full  list  price  and  the  large 
retailer  who  purchases  in  large  quantities  and  resells  at  the  contrac- 
tual minimum  will  typically  obtain  between  30  and  35  percent  as  his 
mark-up.  (The  range  for  all  of  the  manufacturers'  products  in  this 
group  is  considerably  wider  but  these  are  the  most  common  or  "modal" 
margins.)  On  purchases  at  maximum  cost  and  resale  at  the  minimum 
price,  the  typical  mark-up  is  considerably  lower,  ranging  from  20  to 
25  percent,  and  on  purchases  at  minimum  cost  and  resale  at-  the  full 
list  price,  the  typical  mark-up  is  between  40  and  45  percent.  "^' 

The  second  group  into  which  this  manufacturer  divides  his  prod- 
ucts is  composed  largely  of  vitamin  products.  Quantity  discounts 
are  somewhat  smaller  and  mark-ups  materially  more  liberal.  The 
maximum  quantity  discount  for  this  group  is  only  10  percent  instead 
of  15  percent.  The  mark-ups  available  to  the  retailer  for  28  articles 
are  summarized  in  table  45.  On  purchases  at  maximum  cost  and 
resale  at  the  full  list  price  and  also  on  purchases  at  minimum  cost  and 
resale  at  the  contractual  minimum,  the  typical  range  is  between 
35  and  45  percent.  The  small  retailer  purchasing  in  minimum 
quantities  will  typically  obtain  between  30  and  35  percent  as  his 
mark-up  even  on  sales  at  the  contractual  minimum.  The  large 
retailer  taking  advantage  -of  full  quantity  and  cash  discounts  and 
selling  at  the  full  list  price  can  obtain  as  much  as  45  to  50  percent 
mark-up  on  sales  of  most  of  the  items  in  this  group. 


_  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


403 


Table  44. — Maximum  and  minimum  retail  mark-ups  for  1S2  products  sold  by  a 
large   drug   manufacturer — Group   I 


Number  of  items  yielding  specified  mark-ups 

Mark-ups  (in  percentages) 

Ttems  .<?nlf1  at.  minimum 
resale  price- 

Items  sold  at  full 
retail  price- 

To  retailers 

purchasing  at 

maximum 

cost 

To  retailers 

purchasing  at 

minimum 

cost 

To  retailers 

purchasing  at 

maximum 

cost 

To  retailers 

purchasing  at 

minimum 

cost 

10  to  14.9.... 

7 
16 
69 
26 
9 
2 
3 

15  to  19.9 

20  to  24.9.. 

4 
10 
66 
48 
9 
2 
2 
1 

2 
36 
67 
13 
7 
6 
2 

25  to  20.9. 

30to34.9      

J 

35  to  39.9 

10 

40  to  44.9. 

84 

45  to  49.9          

24 

50  to  54.9 

g 

55  to  59.9 - 

4 

Total 

132 

132 

132 

13'> 

Source:  Manufacturer's  Price  List. 


Table  45. — Maximum  and  minimum  retail  mark-ups  for  28  products  sold  by  a  large 
drug  manufacturer — Group  II 


Number  of  items  yielding  specified  mark-ups 

Mark-ups  (in  percentages) 

Items  sold  at  minimum 
resale  price- 

Items  sold  at  full 
retail  price- 

To  retailers 

purchasing  at 

maximum 

cost 

To  retailers 

purchasing  at 

minimum 

cost 

To  retailers 

purchasing  at 

maximum 

cost 

To  retailers 

purchasing  at 

minimmn 

cost 

20  to  24.9 

2 

5 

21 

25  to  29.9 

30  to  34.9 

2 
15 
11 

3 
10 
13 

2 

35  to  39.9 

1 

40to44.9 

7 

45  to  49.9 

18 

50  to  54.9 

2 

Total 

28 

28 

28 

28 

Source:  Manufacturer's  Price  List. 

The  third  group  of  products  offered  by  this  manufacturer  comprises 
primarily  standard  pharmaceuticals  and  biologicals  often  sold  on 
prescription.  Price  competition  for  items  of  this  character  is  rarely 
an  important  factor.  As  a  result,  no  minimum  prices  have  been  estab- 
lished by  contract.  In  all  cases  the  retailer  receives  a  40-percent 
discount  from  the  full  list  price,  plus  an  additional  1  percent  for  cash. 
The  practice  is  to  sell  most  products  of  this  kind  at  the  full  list  price, 
so  that  the  retailer's  mark-up  will  usually  be  about  40  percent  on  all 
sales. 

Mark-ups  for  cosmetics. — Among  the  products  discussed  in  the 
detailed  analysis  of  terms  of  sale,  above,  were  two  brands  of  cos- 
metics. The  mark-up  on  these  items  to  retailers  buying  through 
wholesalers  is  between  34  and  35  percent  in  both  cases.  For  both 
these  items  no  quantity  discounts  were  offered  and  the  minimum  price 
was  established  at  the  full  list  price,  so  that  gross  margins  were  uni- 
form to  all  retailers  who  purchased  through  wholesalers. 

These  two  articles  appear  to  be  generally  representative  of  the 
situation  with  regard  to  most  widely  advertised  cosmetics,  particularly 


404 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


for  those  in  the  higher-priced  lines.  This  is  indicated  by  table  46, 
which  summarizes  the  mark-ups  available  under  different  conditions 
of  sale  and  resale.  (No  allowance  has  been  made  for  cash  discounts, 
but  these  are  never  large.)  For  the  products  of  a  number  of  important 
manufacturers,  33  to  34  percent  appears  to  be  the  standard  mark-up 
under  ordinary  conditions.  Quantity  discounts  are  available  for  the 
products  of  some  of  these  manufacturers  but  they  are  usually  limited 
and  rarely  raise  the  mark-up  above  40  percent.  In  a  few  cases, 
however,  mark-ups  are  considerably  lower,  but  these  appear  to  form 
the  exception  rather  than  the  rule. 

Table  46. — Maximum  and  minimum  retail  mark-ups  allowed  by  12  cosmetic  manu- 
facturers on  their  various  price  lines 


Number  of  items  yielding  specified  mark-ups  • 

Mark-ups  (in  percentages) 

Items  sold  at  minimum 
resale  price- 

Items  sold  at  full 
retail  price- 

To  retailers 

purchasing  at 

maximum 

cost 

To  retailers 

purchasing  at 

rainlmum 

cost 

To  retailers 

purchasing  at 

maximum 

cost 

To  retailers 

purchasing  at 

minimum 

cost 

10  to  14  9 

1 
5 
5 
14 
38 

15  to  19  9                                                         

1 
3 
17 
19 
15 
8 

20  to  24.9                                                 

10 
13 
39 
1 
2 

25  to  29.9                                   --- 

17 

30to34.9                  

23 

35  to  39.9           

11 

40  to  44.9                                   -- 

2 

12 

45  to  49.9                              --- 

50  to  64  9                                                   

2 

........ 

2 

Total..- - 

65 

65 

65 

65 

I  The  "minimum"  retail  and  the  "full  list"  retail  price  were  identical  for  52  of  the  66  items. 
Source:  Wholesaler's  Price  list,  September-October  1939. 

Mark-ups  in  California. — Tables  47  and  48  are  taken  from  a  recent 
study  of  the  effects  of  resale  price  maintenance  in  California.''  These 
indicate  the  percentage  mark-ups  for  different  kinds  of  drug  products. 
Table  47  is  for  all  kinds  of  products,  both  advertised  and  unadvertised, 
while  table  48  is  for  well-known  advertised  drug  products  only.  It  is 
again  evident  that,  despite  considerable  variations  among  different 
kinds  of  products,  there  is  a  marked  tendency  for  retail  margins  to  con- 
centrate in  the  range  between  30  and  35  percent.  Mark-ups  for 
well-known  advertised  products,  however,  are  somewhat  below  the 
average  for  all  products. 

Summary. — The  data  which  have  been  presented  indicate  that 
despite  considerable  variations  in  detail  and  for  particular  products, 
there  is  a  substantial  degree  of  uniformity  of  mark-up  policy  in  the 
drug  trade.  Wholesalers  usually  obtain  a  gross  margin  slightly 
exceeding  15  percent  on  the  sale  of  most  transactions.  In  the  case  of 
some  products,  wholesalers'  mark-ups  are  narrower  on  sales  of  large 
quantities  than  on  sales  of  small  quantities,  but  this  is  far  from  the 
universal  rule.  Moreover,  it  has  been  pointed  out  that  the  average 
small  drug  retailer  usually  buys  on  a  hand-to-mouth  basis,  so  that 
any  quantity  discounts  are  only  applicable  to  the  minority  of  transac- 
tions. 

•  Price  Control  Under  Fair  Trade  Legislation,  by  Ewald  T.  Qrether,  pp.  94-96. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EXIJONOMIC  POWER 


405 


For  the  drug  retailer  the  typical  gross  margin  seems  to  be  between 
30  and  35  percent  of  the  selling  price.  The  figure  is  probably  some- 
what below  this  range  for  popular  fast-selling  merchandise  on  which 
there  is  active  price  competition,  and  somewhat  higher  for  slow- 
mpving  articles  such  as  standard  pharmaceuticals  and  biologicals. 
It  seems  probable,  moreover,  that  the  difference  between  the  prices 
at  which  large  and  small  retailers  can  purchase  is  reflected  not  so 
much  in  a  corresponding  difference  in  their  gross  margins  as  in  their 
resale  price  policies.  The  sm^all  retailor  pays  more,  but  usually  sells 
for  more,  with  the  result  that  liis  rrark-up  is  probably  much  the  same 
as  that  of  his  larger  competitor. 

Table  47. — Retail  margins  '  on  products  in  the  drug  trade  in  California  under  the 
California  fair-trade  law,  July  19S6 


Classes  of  products 


Num- 
ber of 
items 


Percent  of  minimum  margins  in  percentage  intervals 


0-10.9      11-20.9    21-30.9    31-10.9    41-50.9    61-60.9    61-70.9 


Aggre- 
gate 
mini- 
mum 

margins 


Aggre- 
gate 
maxi- 
mum 
margins 


Ant,  fly.  and  in- 
sect supplies 

Antisppiips 

Atomizers  and  va- 
porizers.    

Baby  specialties 

Cigars 

Cod  liver  oil 

Contraceptives 

Cosmetics    

Cough  and  cold 
preparations 

Dentifrices 

Deodorants 

Dog  and  bird  pre- 
parations  

Effervescent  salts. . 

Eye  preparations... 

Films 

Foods  and  tonics... 

Foot  remedies  and 
preparations 

Hair  preparations . . 

Hospiial  supplies... 

Household  reme- 
dies  

Household  supplies. 

Laxatives 

Liniments. 

Mineral  oils 

Mineral  waters 

Nose  and  throat 
preparations 

Ointments 

Patents 

Pharmaceuticals . . . 

Pilbs  and  tablets 

Poison  oak  and  in- 
sect lotions 

Razors  and  blades. 

Rubber  goods 

Salts 

Shaving  supplies... 

Soaps.. 

Sundries 

Suppositories 

Tooth  and  gum 
treatments _. 

Tooth  brushes 

Vaseline  (petrole- 
um jellies) 

Watches  and  clocks. 

Total' 


32 
61 

29 
7 

43 
120 

74 
359 

63 
45 
20 


30 
15 
21 
76 

43 
99 
62 

37 
27 
91 
25 
30 
3 

50 
55 
23 
64 
161 

11 

47 
20 
10 
88 
24 
46 
10 

24 
16 

26 
37 


2,112 


4.92 


2.51 

1.89 

22.22 

5.00 


21.87 
18.03 


2«.57 
37.21 
10.83 
1.35 
18.10 

13.21 
35.56 
30.00 


.3.33 

33.33" 

6.67 

14.28 

14.29 

6.58 

14.47 

2.32 

6.06 

46.47 

12.90 

5.40 

7.41 

18.62 

1.10 

8.79 

4.00 

20.00 

6.67 

23.33 

2.00 

1.82 

10.91 

8.69 

1.66 

14.06 

10.60 

6.38 

10.64 

3.41 

52.27 

25.00 

10.00 

"25."66" 

7.69 

15.63 
39.35 

24.14 
71.43 
58.14 
67.60 
27.03 
31.75 

39.62 
22.22 
45.00 

12.50 
33.  34 
3.3.33 
71.43 
55.26 

26.68 
30.30 
6.45 

18.92 
22.22 
42.86 
62.00 
26.67 
66.67 

40.00 
40.00 
82.61 
42.19 
41.72 

9.09 
29.79 

5.00 
30.00 
26.14 
29.17 

6.52 
40.00 

.54.17 
37.  .50 

65.38 
70.27 


34.37 
19.67 


4.66 
16.67 
31.08 
38.44 

26.42 
6.67 
20.00 

87.50 
16.67 
26.67 


11.84 

20.93 
14.14 
80.65 

40.54 
48.15 
18.68 
12.00 
30.00 
33.33 

38.00 
29.09 
8.70 
31.25 
30.46 

27.27 
53.19 
50.00 
50.00 
3.41 
20.83 
45.65 
30.00 

20.83 
18.75 

23.08 
27.03 


16.48       36.60       28.66 


25.00 
18.03 


3.13 


6.90 


10.83 
24.32 
7.80 

15.09 


4.17 

10.81 

.56 

3.77 
4.44 


13.33 
33.33 


10.63 


48.84 
3.03 


27.03 


20.88 
8.00 
13.33 


16.00 
18.18 


9.38 
16.23 


63.64 


40.00 
10.00 
10.23 
20.83 
19.67 
20.00 

16.67 
18.76 

3.85 
2.70 


1.32 
2.33 


6.41 
3.70 
6.69 
4.00 


4.00 


1.56 


5.00 
10.00 
2.27 
4.17 
28.26 


2.56 


5.41 
.84 


2.70 


1.10 


1.99 


4.16 


.71 


31.31 
27.60 

33.38 
22.62 
24.40 
29.25 
40.59 
32.  74 

29.14 
21.60 
24.26 

35.64 
26.40 
32.94 
20.74 
30.63 

38.16 
23.28 
34.29 

38.06 
28.56 
36.83 
26.96 
27.73 
31.64 

30.88 
30.46 
24.97 
31.51 
31.07 

40.48 
29.76 
42.14 
39.95 
29.12 
37.18 
38.30 
31.47 

31.16 
28.63 

27.23 
32.48 


31.73 


37.04 
33.66 

39.32 
29.38 
27.60 
31.89 
48.01 
36.11 

36.54 
26.41 
29.56 

41.96 
30.  52 
38.99 
29.  .51 
34.13 

44.02 
28.76 
39.16 

42.61 
34.41 
39.38 
36.39 
27.31 
38.43 

37.83 
36.65 
33.62 
33.93 
36.82 

45.54 
30.63 
47.83 
42.25 
33.06 
40.22 
42.28 
38.93 

37.91 
38.27 

29.96 
35.53 


35.84 


'  Margins  are  computed  as  percentages  of  contractual  prices. 

'  Total  percentages  are  aggregates,  not  averages  of  the  class  percentages. 

Source:  Table  VII,  Price  control  under  fair-trade  legislation,  by  Orether,  appendix  B,  pp.  48^-483. 


406 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table   48. — Minimum  retail  margins '   on  8electe4  well  known  advertised  drug 
products  in  California  under  the  California  fair-trade  law,  July  19S6 


Number 

of 

items 

Percent  of  items  in  percentage  intervals 

Class 
averages 

of 
selected 

items 

Total 
class 

Classes  of  products 

0-10.0 

11-20.9 

21-309 

31-40.9 

41-60.9 

61-60.9 

averages 
(see  table 

vn) 

Antiseptics 

12 

7 
28 

6 
14 
4 
3 
1 
4 
1 
8 
2 
4 
1 
3 
2 
4 
2 
2 

3 
17 

""7."i4' 

50  00 
28.58 
42.86 

4L67 
28.58 
17.86 

80  00 
21.42 
60.00 
66. 67 
100.00 
76.00 

8.33 
14.28 
25.00 

20.00 

20  67 
31.36 
26.21 

28.68 
15.63 
20  82 
25.00 
23.50 
24.25 
33.00 
20.29 
23.95 
26.52 
19.70 
25.87 
30  00 
20.97 
25.50 
28.15 

27.73 
17.95 

27.60 

Cod-liver  oil 

14.28 
7.14 

14.28 

29.25 

HOSTTlBti'*-'' 

32.74 

Cough  and  cold  prep- 
arations   

29.14 

Dentifrices 

28.68 

60.00 
50.00 
33.33 

21.60 

Deodorants 

24.26 

Effervescent  salts 

26.40 

Eye  preparations 

32.94 

Foods,  tonics,  etc 

25.00 

30.63 

Foot  remedies     

100.00 

38.15 

Hair  preparations 

12.50 

37.50 

50  00 
100.00 
75.00 

23.28- 

Household  remedies. . 

38.06 

Laxatives 

"33.33" 

26.00 
100.00 

35.83 

Liniments 

26.67 

Mineral  oUs 

33.33 
50  00 
76.00 
100.00 
60.00 

66.67 
17.66 

"50.06' 

33.34 

27.73 

Nasal  preparations 

30.88. 

Oiatments 

25.00 

30.46 

Patents 

24.97 

Pharmaceuticals- 

50.00 
33.33 

31.16 

puis,     tablets,     and 
capsules.. 

31.07 

Shaving  supplies 

82.34 

29.12 

Total' 

127 

7.05 

■39.41 

38.62 

11.01 

3.13 

.78 

22.76 

30  9» 

1  Margins  are  computed  as  percentages  of  contractual  prices. 
>  Total  percentages  are  aggregates. 

Source:  Table  Xin,  Price  control  under  fair-trade  legislation,  by  Orether,  appendix  B,  pp.  494-495. 

None  of  these  figures  take  account  of  any  special  privileges  granted 
to  very  large  buyers  such  as  the  national  chain  stores,  but  data 
regarding  such  special  concessions  are  very  difficult  to  obtain,  especi- 
ally since  the  Robinson-Patman  Act  became  law.  Where  such  special 
concessions  are  available,  margins  may  be  correspondingly  wider, 
especially  for  commodities  for  which  resale  price  maintenance  contracts 
have  been  issued. 

It  has  also  been  impossible  to  obtain  any  information  regarding 
margins  for  private  brands.  The  very  marked  differences  which  have 
been  demonstrated  between  the  cost  of  widely  advertised  products  to 
distributors  and  the  cost  of  producing  similar  items  from  their  chemical 
ingredients  may  make  it  possible  for  the  owners  of  private  brands  to 
resell  them  to  the  consumer  at  levels  considerably  below  those  for  the 
correspondingly  nationally  advertised  merchandise,  h,Ad  yet  to  recover 
a  very  substantial  margin  on  the  transaction. 


INDEX 

ADVERTISING:  Pag& 

Allowances __      _     _.  100 

Brand.     (»See  BRANDS  AND  TRADE-MARKS.) 

Consumer  guides,  criticism  of 106 

Mass  demand  created  may  affect  costs  of  manufacture 106- 

Nonprice  competition 75 

Price  rigidity  and;  comment  and  chart  61 . 84 

AGRICULTURAL  COMMODITIES:  Geographic  price  structures.      """  287 

AGRICULTURAL  IMPLEMENTS  AND   MACHINERY:  Geographic 

price     structures 33I 

ALUMINUM:  Geographic  price  structure __               .       __  338 

AMERICAN  RETAIL  FEDERATION:  Congressional  inquiry           '"  100 

APPAREL.     (See  WEARING  APPAREL.) 

AUTOMOBILE  INDUSTRY: 

Geographic  price  structure 33O 

Replacement  rate  of  passenger  cars;  obsolescence  factor  versus  dura- 
bility  150 

Trade-in  allowances..^ _    _        _      __      150-151 

Cash  value,  1933-38;  table  23 '  163 

AUTOMOBILE  TIRES:  Wholesale  price  and  average  life  of,   1913-38; 

chart  8  and  table _         65  258 

BAKELITE.     (5ee  PLASTICS.)                                                                  ""  ' 

BASING-POINT  PRICING: 

Benzol 3,J8 

Cement 311 

Chem  icals 320 

Flooring,  maple  and  oak 309 

Gasoline 341 

Lead 339 

Products  subject  to 345 

Southern  pine 309 

Steel 305 

Sugar 295 

Systems 279 

Tactics 8 

Zinc -  338 

BLAIR,  JOHN  M.,  joint  avthor  (See  KEIM,  WALTER  G.). 

BOOMS.     (See  RECESSION  AND  RECOVERY.) 

BOOTS  AND  SHOES,  Geographic  price  structure . 303 

BRANDS  AND  TRADE- MARKS: 

Advertised  and  substitute  brands 368 

Brand  prestige 7 

Canned  foods,  prices  and  quality  grades,  brand  comparison;  table  4--  77 

Consumer  brand  preference  questionnaire,  T.  N.  E.  C 78 

.National    Brands    Week,    drug   trade . 380 

Nonprice  competition,  trade-marks 75 

Price  at  wholesale  of  identical  substances  sold  under  proprietary  and 

nonproprietary  names,  brand  comparison;  table  6 '  81 

Price  flexibility,  relation  to  brand  preference;  table  8  and  chart  11 86-87 

Price  rigidity  and  advertising  relationship;  comment  and  chart  9 84 

BREAD:   Geographic  price  structure 295 

BREAKFAST  CEREALS:  Prices,  1926^37,  cents  per  pound,  retail,  whole- 
sale, and  margins,  farm  value;  chart  10 85 

BRICK:  Wholesale  price  index;  chart  1  and  table  (by  months),  1926-39__  24,  252 

247149 — 41 — No.  1 28  407 


408  INDEX 

Page 
BROWN,  LAURA  MAE,  Conventional  Price  Lines,  appendix  II,  prepared 

by 242 

Joint  author.      (See  NELSON,  SAUL.) 
BUILDING  CONSTRUCTION:  Interrelated  character  of  interests,  ma- 
terials producers,  labor,  financial  agencies,  cause  of  inertia  in  incentive; 

proposal _.__.  52 

BUILDING  MATERIALS: 

Geographic  price  structure . 310 

Lumber  products.     {See  LUMBER.) 

Steel  products.     (See  STEEL  INDUSTRY.) 

BURNS,  ARTHUR  R.     Decline  of  competition;   cited  (n.) 5 

BUSINESS  CYCLE.     (See  also  RECESSION  AND  RECOVERY.) 

Price  policy,  effect  upon  recession  and  recovery 10 

BUSINESS  FURNITURE  AND  EQUIPMENT: 

Geographic  price  structure 316,  336 

Small  versus  large  manufacturers'  confiicfr-over  price  and/or  nonprice 

competition 92 

BUYERS: 

Individual.     (See  CONSUMER  ECONOMY.) 

Institutional,  industrial,  or  governmental,  expertness  of ; 75 

CALIFORNIA:   Minimum  resale  price  law  of  1933 353 

CANADA:    ROYAL    COMMISSION    ON    PRICE    SPREADS,    report 

cited  (n) .; 17 

CARBON  BLACK: 

Price  structure 317 

Zone  prices  and  differentials;  table 321 

CATTLE:  Geographic  price  structure 290 

CEMENT:  Geographic  price  structure 311 

CHAIN  DRUG  STORES.     (See  DRUG  TRADE.) 

CHEMICALS:  Geographic  price  structure -_.  316,  321 

CHOCOLATE  BARS:  Price  lining;  change  in  size  of  bar;  table  3 73 

C  [GARETTES :  Geographic  price  structure 304 

COAL;    ANTHRACITE:    Wholesale    price   index,    1926-39;    comment, 

chart  3  and  table  (by  mos.) 26-27,  254 

GOAL;  BITUMINOUS:  Geographic  price  structure 342 

COFFEE:  Geographic  price  structure 298 

COLUMBUS,  OHIO:  Drug  trade  study,  by  Marketing  Laws  Survey 365 

COMPETITIVE  STRATEGY: 

Emphasis  shifting  to  nonprice  channels 19 

Nonprice  competition.     (See  NONPRICE  COMPETITION.) 
Price  competition.     (See  PRICE  COMPETITION.) 

Redirection  of 59 

Sales.     (See  SALES  STRATEGY.) 
COMPTOMETERS.     (See   BUSINESS   FURNITURE   AND   EQUIP- 
MENT.) 
CONCENTRATION  IN  INDUSTRY:  Electrical  household  equipment; 

comment  and  table  22 134,  163 

CONSUMER  ECONOMY: 

Average  expenditures  for  household  electrical  equipment,  by  income 

levels;  table  13 130 

Brand    preference    questionnaire,     Temporary     National    Economic 

Committee 78 

Buyer  preference:  complicated  by  nonprice  competition 56 

Role  of ^^ 6 

Consumer  purchases  study,  by  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  and  co- 
operating agencies ;  cited ' 120 

Effect  of  consumer  movement  on  character  of  information  regarding 

retail  commodities 57 

Expenditures  by  wage  earner  and  clerical  worker  families  for  electric 
refrigerators,    washing    machines,    vacuum    cleaners    and    electric 

stovcs  and  hot  plates,  by  economic  level  of  families;  table  24-. 164 

Government  program  for  consumer  education 108 

Household  equipment  ownership  by  income  groups;   charts    17-24, 

tables 122-129,  263^-264 

Income  residual  after  primary  expenditures,  by  income  groups,  1935- 

36;  table 265 

Income  residuals,  budgeting  of,  comment  and  charts  25-26 130-33 


INDEX  409 

CONSUMER  ECONOMY— Continued.  Page 
Organized  consumer  movement  reflects  dissatisfaction  with  adver- 
tising reliability 106 

Organizations  supplying  technical  guides;  cited  (n.) 77 

Purchasing  guides,  criticism  of 106 

Price  lines ;  consumer  accommodation 70 

Price  lining  consumers'  durable  goods 249 

Quality  v.  price  criteria  and  consumer  demand 66 

COPPER:  Geographic  price  structure.^ 340 

COPPER  REFINERIES:  Location  of 340 

COSMETICS:  Geographic  price  structure 323 

COST  ACCOUNTING: 

Uniform  cost  accounting  and  price  control 9 

COST  DATA: 

Distribution  cost: 

Electrical  equipment  industries 143 

Food  distribution   by   farmer;   index   (1910-14=100),    1913-38; 

table ----         49 

Washing  machines 144 

Freight  costs.     {See  FREIGHT  COSTS.) 
Production  cost: 

Electric-equipment  industries 143 

Production,  Transportation,  and  Distribution  Costs: 

Estimate,  1929 271 

COST  RELATIONSHIP:  Cost-price  relation 34,50 

COTTON  GOODS:  Wholesale  price  index,   1926-39;  comment,  chart  2 

and  table  (by  months) 23,  25,  253 

COTTONSEED:  Geographic  price  structure 292 

COTTONSEED  OIL:  Geographic  price  structure 295 

CREDIT.     {See  NONPRICE  COMPETITION.) 
DEMAND  FACTOR: 

Inelastic  versus  joint  demand : 

Inelastic 51 

Mass  demand  created  by  advertising  may  affect  cost  of  manufacture.       106 

Price  relationship  and 42 

Quality  versus  price  criteria  and  consumer  demand ._         66 

DEPRESSIONS.     {See  RECESSION  AND  RECOVERY.) 

DIFFERENTIATED  PRODUCTS:  Standard  products   v 7 

DISTRIBUTION: 

Cost.     {See  COST  DATA.) 

Legislation  for  protection  of  desirability  questionable,  certain  con- 
ditions under : 14 

DOORS :  Geographic  price  structure 309 

DOUGLAS  FIR :  Geographic  price  structure 308 

DRUG  TRADE: 

Chain-store  retail  price  trends  compared  w^ith  independents 361 

Distributive  margins ■ —  386 

Columbus,  Ohio,  marketing  laws,  survey  study 366 

Geographic  price  structure 323 

National  Brands  Week 380 

Price  differentials: 

"Cost  to  buy  versus  cost  to  make" 369-71 

Nationally  advertised  versus  substitute 371 

Price  lines,  retail 382 

Resale  price  maintenance  legislation,  effect  on  relationship  between 

nationally  advertised  and  substitute  merchandise 379 

Retail  market,  general  characteristics 351 

Retail  price  trends: 

Chains  versus  independents 361 

Six  selected  products 355 

DURABILITY  FACTOR: 

Automobile  tires.     {See  AUTOMOBILE  TIRES.) 

Refrigerators,  electric 149 

EGGS:  Wholesale  price  index,  1926-39;  comment,  chart  2  and  table  (by 

months) 23,  25,  253 

ELECTRIC  FANS :  Geographic  price  structure 333 

ELECTRIC  FARM  AND  HOME  AUTHORITY:  Function  of 159-60 


410  INDEX 

ELECTRICAL  HOUSEHOLD  EQUIPMENT:  Page 

Concentration  of  industry;  comment  and  table  22 134,  163 

Cost  data: 

Distribution  cost 143 

Production  cost,  paucity  of  information 143 

Geographic  price  structure 33& 

Ownership  by  family  income  groups,  1935-36;  refrigerators,  washing 

machines,  vacuum  cleaners,  radios;  charts  17-24,  and  tables 122-129, 

263-264 

Price  and  sales  policy  analysis 109 

Purchases  by  families  participating  in  Rural  Electrification  Admin- 
istration programs 160 

Radios.     {See  RADIOS.) 

Refrigerators.     (See  REFRIGERATORS.) 

Statistics: 

1925-38  market  saturation;  percentage  of  wired  homes  owning 

each  of  four  tvpes  of  equipment,  table  11 118 

1929-37,  average  retail  value  and  sales,  1929,  1932,  1937;  table  10.       112 
Vacuum  cleaners.     (See  VACUUM  CLEANERS.) 
Washing  machines.     {See  WASHING  MACHINES.) 
ELECTRICAL   MACHINERY  AND   APPARATUS:  Geographic  price 

structures 332 

ENGINES:  Geographic  price  structure,  Diesel  and  gasoline  engines 335^ 

EXCAVATING   MACHINERY:  Geographic  price  structure 336 

FAIR  TRADE  ACTS: 

Desirability  questionable  under  certain  conditions 14 

Effect  on  nonprice  competition 56 

Effect  on  retail  price  competition 8& 

Effect  on  system  of  distribution 52 

Independent  retailers  versus  manufacturers  attitude 90 

Price  maintenance  contracts   between  trade-mark  owner    and    dis- 
tributors           86 

States  in  which  not  operative 354 

FAMILY  ECONOMY.     {See  CONSUMER  ECONOMY.) 
FARM  PURCHASING  POWER: 

Effect  of  shift  in 47 

Statistics: 

1913-38.     Selected  indexes  of  prices  paid  by  farmers,  farm  wage 
rates,  costs  of  distribution,  farm  taxes,  and  mortgage  interest; 

table  2 

FEDERAL  HOUSING  ADMINISTRATION.     Modernization  loans  in         49 

effect  1934-37 159 

FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION: 

Agricultural  income  inquiry ;  cited  (n.) 289 

Price   base   inquiry,   the  basing-point  formula  and    cement    prices; 

cited  (n.) 273 

Report  on  certain  phases  of  the  fertilizer  industry;  cited  (n.) 99 

FERRO-ALLOYS :  Geographic  price  structure 308 

FERTILIZERS: 

Geographic  price  structure 324 

Prices,  nominal  versus  actual;    Federal    Trade    Commission    report 

extract 99 

Zone  pricing 283 

FLOOR  TILE:  Geographic  price  structure 312 

FLOORING :  Geographic  price  structure. -. 309 

FOOD  PRODUCTS:  Geographic  price  structure 294 

FOOTWEAR.     (See  BOOTS  AND  SHOES.) 

FREIGHT  COSTS:  Freight  bill  data  inadequate 271 

FREIGHT  EQUALIZATION  STRUCTURE: 

Binder  twine 302 

Chemicals 318 

Floor  tile 312 

Gasoline 34 1 

Gypsum  plaster 312 

Lime 311 

Operation  of ' 276 

Products  subject  to 344 


INDEX  411 

FRENCH,  WILLIAM  C,  JR.,  joint  author.     (See  NELSON,  SAUL.)  Page 

FRUITS :  Geographic  price  structure 292 

FURNITURE:  BUSINESS.     (See     BUSINESS     FURNITURE     AND 

EQUIPMENT.) 
FURNITURE,  HOUSEHOLD: 

Electrical  equipment.     (See  ELECTRICAL  HOUSEHOLD  EQUIP- 
MENT.) 

Geographic  price  structure 315 

GALBRAITH,  J.  K.:  Monopoly  power  and  price  rigidities:  cited  (n.) 16 

GARMENT  INDUSTRY.     (See  WEARING  APPAREL.) 

"GARY  DINNERS" 279 

GASOLINE :  Geographic  price  structure 341 

GENERAL   MOTORS  CORPORATION:  Dynamics  of  automobile  de- 
mand; cited  (n.) 64 

GEOGRAPHIC  PRICE  STRUCTURES:  Buyer  and  seller  dominated- .  284 

GLASS  CONTAINER  INDUSTRY:  Price  control 8 

GOVERNMENT  NONREGULATORY  ACTIVITY: 

Credit  activities  of  Federal  agencies 141 

Electrical  equipment  purchases  facilitated  by  various  agencies 159-160 

Expansion  of  potential  electrical  appliance  market  by  Rural  Electri- 
fication Administration 111 

Financing  sales  of  electrical  equipment  by  Electric  Home  and  Farm 

Authority 111 

Insurance  of  loans  for  purchase  of  electrical  equipment  by  Federal 

Housing  Administration 111 

GOVERNMENT  REGULATION: 

Combating  food  and  drug  misrepresentation  and  mislabeling 58 

Commodity  standardization  development 108 

Informative  commodity  labeling 108 

Price,  effect  on  nonprice  competition ■_ 56 

Price  competition 62 

Price  maintenance,  effect  on  system  of  distribution . 52 

Standardization  of  commodities  and  materials.  National  Bureau  of 

Standards 58 

GRETHER,  EWALD  T.:    Price  control  under  fair-trade  legislation;   ex- 
tract   369 

GYPSUM  PLASTER:  Geographic  price  structure 312 

HANDLER,  MILTON:  Unfair  competition;  cited  (n.) 107 

HARD  FIBERS  AND  PRODUCTS:  Geographic  price  structure 302 

HARDWARE:  Geographic  price  structure 308,334 

HEATING  EQUIPMENT:    Geographic  price  structure,  boilers  and  ra- 
diation    313 

HOUSEHOLD  FURNITURE.     (See  FURNITURE.) 

HUMPHREY,  DON  D.:  Nature  and  meaning  of  rigid  nrices;  cited  (n.)..  18 

INDUSTRIAL  BENZOL:  Geographic  price  structure 318 

INSULATION  BOARD:  Geographic  price  structure 313 

INVESTMENT:  Price  relationship 43 

IRON  ORE:  Geographic  price  structure 308 

KALOCKI,  MICHAEL:  Theory  of  commodity  income  and  capital  taxa- 
tion; cited  (n.) 59 

KEIM,  WALTER  G.  and  JOHN  M.  BLAIR:  Electrical  equipment  in- 
dustries— an  illustrative  case,  chap.  IV;  prepared  by 109 

Joint  author.     (See  NELSON,  SAUL.) 

KENNEDY,  STEPHEN  JAY:  Profits  and  losses  in  textiles;  cited  (n.).._  73 

KREPS,  T.  J.:  Economic  problems  in  a  changing  world;  cited  (n.) 36 

LADDERS:  Geographic  price  structure 309 

LAMINATED  PHENOLIC  PRODUCTS.     (See  PLASTICS.) 334 

LEAD:  Geographic  price  structure 339 

LERNER,  A.  P.:  Concept  of  monopoly  and  the  measurement  of  monopoly 

powers ;  cited  (n.) 59 

LIFE  EXPECTANCY  OF  COMMODITIES: 

Automobile  tires 65,  258 

Refrigerators,  electric 149 

LIME:  Geographic  price  structure 311 

LINSEED  OIL:  Geographic  price  structure 314 

LUMBER:  Geographic  price  structure 308 

MACHINE  TOOLS:  Geographic  price  structure,  milling,  grinding,  screw 

machines,  etc 335 


412  INDEX 

Page 

MACHINERY:  Geographic  price  structures 331 

MAHOGANY:  Geographic  price  structure 309 

MANILA  ROPE:  Geographic  price  structure 302 

MARKET  SATURATION: 

Income-group  relationships 120 

Replacement-sales  significance 148 

Sales  and — 

Refrigerators,  washing  machines,  vacuum  cleaners,  and  ranges; 

number  sold,  percent  of  homes  using,  1925-38;  table  11 118 

Refrigerators,  washing  machines,  vacuum  cleaners,  ranges;  num- 
ber sold,  percent  homes  using,  1927-38;  chart  16  and  table.-  119,  262 
Refrigerators,  washing  machines,  and  vacuum  cleaners;  percent 
saturation  change,    1937  of   1929;  percent  sales,    1937-38  of 

1932-33;  table  12 118 

MARKETING-LAWS  SURVEY,  W.  P.  A.:  Columbus,  Ohio,  drugstores.  365 
MAANS,  GARDINER  C: 

Industrial  prices  and  their  relative  inflexibility;  cited  (n.) 17,  31   37 

Notes  on  inflexible  prices;  cited  (n.) 18 

MEATS:  Geographic  price  structure ..  294 

MILK:  Geographic  price  structure 290 

MILLER-TYDINGS  ACT: 

Effect  on  system  of  distribution 52 

Interstate  price- maintenance  contracts 86 

Provisions  of 354 

MOISE,  IRWIN  S.,  AND  GEORGE   B.  HADDOCK:   Manufacturers' 

control  of  distribution;  cited  (n.) 297 

MUND,  VERNON  A.:   "Freight  allowed"  method  of  price  quotation; 

cited  (n.) 282 

NATIONAL  INDUSTRIAL  CONFERENCE  BOARD:  BuUetin  5,  vol. 

13.     Price  flexibilitv  and  change  in  production;  cited  (n.) 38 

NATIONAL  RECOVERY  ADMINISTRATION: 
Codes : 

Retail  drug  trade .' 353 

Types  of  concessions  to  influence  sales  as  dealt  with  by  codes.  _  94 
Division    of    Industrial    Economics:  Minimum    price    control,    staff 

study ;  extract 91 

Division  of  Review:  Work  materials.     No.  62.     Moise  and  Haddock, 

Manufacturers'  control  of  distribution;  cited  (n.) 29? 

Most  comprehensive  regulation  of  trade  practices  by  Government 62 

Price  reduction  alternative  schemes  devised  by  industry 56 

NATIONAL  RESOURCES  COMMITTEE:  Structure  of  the  American 

economy;  cited  (n.) 30 

NELSON,  SAUL: 

Nonprice  competition,  chapter  III,  prepared  by - 54 

Price  flexibility,  chapter  II,  prepared  by 11 

-. —  AND  LAURA  MAE  BROWN.     Prices  and  price  margins  in  the 

drug  trade ;  part  III,  prepared  by 348 

AND  WILLIAM  C.  FRENCH,  JR.     Geographic  pMce  structures, 

Part  II,  prepared  by 267 

AND  WALTER  G.  KEIM.     Measures  of  price  flexibility;  Appen- 
dix 1,  prepared  by 165 

.     Price  behavior  and  business  policy,  written  by XVII 

NONFERROUS  METALS.     Geographic  price  Structure 338 

NONPRICE  COMPETITION:' 

Advertising  criticism  of  consumer  guides 106 

Borderline  transactions 63 

Brand  emphasis,  net  effect  of ^^-  106 

Brands  a  major  aspect 90 

Business    furniture,   small  versus   large  manufacturer's  conflict  over 

price  and/or  nonprice  competition 92 

Credit  terms ;  electrical-equipment  industries 141 

Garment  trades 9 

Guaranties ;  electrical-equipment  industries 140 

Market  position  maintenance  through  nonprice  v.  price  competition.  _  59 

Quality  criteria 66 


INDEX  413 

NONPRICE  COMPETITION— Continued. 

Quality  emphasis:  Page 

Net  effect  of lOa 

Refrigerator  industry 138 

Small  V.  large  concerns'  escape  devices 90 

Techniques i 54 

Types  of  concessions  to  influence  sales  as  dealt  with  by  N.  R.  A. 

OFFICE  FURNITURE  'aND  EQUIPMENTV  '  {See  BifsiNESS 'FUR- 
NITURE AND  EQUIPMENT.) 

PAINTS:   (Geographic  price  structure 314 

PAPER:  Zone  pricing 283 

PAPER  AND  PULP  INDUSTRIES:  Geographic  price  structure 328 

PATENT  POOLS.     Price  control  and .. 8 

PATENTS:   Importance  of  in  electrical  equipment  industry 134-135 

PETROLEUM  AND  PRODUCTS:  Geographic  price  structure 341 

PHOSPHATE  ROCK:   Wholesale  price  index,  1926-39;  comment,  chart  3 

and  table  (by  months) 26-27,  254 

PITTSBURGH-PLUS  SYSTEM 279 

PLASTERBOARD  INDUSTRY:  Price  control 8 

PLASTICS:   Geograohic  price  structure -._ 334 

PLUMBING  FIXTURES:  Geographic  price  structure. 314 

PLYWOOD:  Geographic  price  structure 310 

PONDEROSA  PINE:  Geographic  price  structure 309 

"POSTAGE  STAMP"  PRICING 282 

Chemicals 319 

POTASH:   Geographic  price  structure 326 

POTASH  SALTS:   Wholesale  price  index,  1929-38;  comment,  chart  3  and 

table  (hv  months).. 26-27,  255 

POTATOES: 

Geographic  price  structure ^ 290 

Wholesale  price  index,  1926-39;  comment,  chart  3  and  table  (by 

months) 26-27,254 

PRICE  COMPETITION: 

Border-line  transactions 63 

Business  furniture,  small  versus  large  manufacturers,  conflict  over 

price  and/or  nonprice  competition.' 92 

Cutting  prices  versus  nominal  quotation 36 

Eff'ect  of  fair-trade  legislation  on  retail-price  competition 88 

Electrical  household  equipment  industry 134 

Market  position  maintenance  through  price  versus  nonprice  competi- 
tion   59 

Techniques 7 

PRICE  CONTROL: 

Basing  point  systems.     (See  BASING  POINT  PRICING.) 

Glass  container  industry 8 

Licensing  agreements 8 

Open-price  systems 9 

Patent  pools 8 

Plasterboard  industry 8 

Price  leadership.     (See  PRICE  LEADERSHIP.) 

Tactics 6 

Uniform  cost  accounting 9 

PRICE  DATA: 

Published  quotations  versus  deviations  on  basis  of  long-term  contracts.  99 

Wholesale  versus  retail,  relative  availability  and  comparability 49-50 

PRICE  DIFFERENTIAL: 

Branded  versus  nonbranded  chemical  products  of  identical  composi- 
tion ;  table 81 

Retail  price  of  drugs,  cosmetics,  and  foods  compared  with  cost  of 

ingredients;  table 82-83 

PRICE  DISPERSION: 

Industrial  production  and;  indexes;  chart  7  (1928-40)  and  table  (1928- 

39) . 46,258 

Industrial  production  and  reciprocals  of  price  dispersion,  wholesale 
prices  of  30  basic  commodities,  1926-39,  index;  comment,  chart  6 

and  table  (by  months) 43-44,257 

References  to  literature  on_. 45 

W.  P.  A.  study •---- -  45- 


414  INDEX 

PRICE  LEADERSHIP:  Page 

Lead  industry 339 

Salt  industry - .^ 297 

Tactics 8 

PRICE  LINING: 

Chocolate  bars;  change  in  size  of  bars;  table  3 73 

Consumers  durable  goods 249 

Consumer  purchase  problems  simplified  by 102 

Drugs,  toiletries,  and  sundries 382 

Retail  markets: 

Wearing  apparel,  women's  and  girls'  and  men's  shirts 243 

Yard  goods 248 

Undesira'ble  features  of 102 

Wholesale  markets: 

Wearing  apparel 242 

Wholesale  v.  retail  markets 70 

PRICE  MAINTENANCE: 
Drug  trade: 

Resale  price  controls 352 

Substitute  brands  and  resale  price  maintenance 379 

Legislation : 

Effect  on  nonprice  competition 56 

Effect  on  retail  price  competition 88 

Effect  of  on  system  of  distribution 52 

Miller-Tydings  Act  provisions 354 

States  in  which  Fair  Trade  Acts  are  not  operative 354 

Trade-mark  owner-distributor  contracts 86 

PRICE  RELATIONSHIPS: 

Brand  preference  to  price  flexibility ;  table  8  and  chart  11 86-87 

Cost-price  relation 34,  50 

Demand  and 42 

Durability  and  price;  wholesale  price  of  automobile  tires  and  average 

life  of  tire,  1913-18;  chart  8  and  table 65,  258 

Production  and 38 

Changes  in  average  wholesale  price  and  quantity  available  for 
consumption  for  111  named  durable,  semidurable,  and  nondu- 
rable commodities;  percent  change  1929-33;  table 255 

Farm  products,  1926-38;  index;  comment,  chart  5  and  table 41,  256 

Median  change  in  price  and  quantity  available  for  consumption, 
1922-33,  durable,  semidurable,  and  nondurable  goods;  com- 
ment, table  and  chart  4 38-39 

Spending  and  investment 42 

PRICE  RESPONSE  TO  MARKET  CONDITIONS:  Literature  on 16 

PRICE  RIGIDITY  AND/OR  FLEXIBILITY: 

Advertising  and;  comment  and  chart  9 84 

Correlation  tables  of  wholesale  price  flexibility;  tables  27-58 211-241 

Expansion  of  rigidity  sector  in  price  universe 19 

Flexibility  measures;  Appendix  I,  prepared  by  Nelson  and  Keim 165 

Flexibility    of    commodity    prices    measured    by    various    criteria; 

table  25 172-189 

Flexibility  of  commodity  prices  measured  by  various  criteria  ranked 

in  order  of  increasing  flexibility;  table  26 190-210 

Flexibility,  provocation  of 11 

Flexibility  relation  to  brand  preference;  table  8  and  chart  11 86-87 

Measurement  of  flexibility 27 

Rigid  or  insensitive  v.  flexible  or  sensitive- 11 

Rigidity: 

Effect  of  technological  change  on 11 

Effect  upon  economy  during  depression  and  boom  periods 12 

Provocation  of 11 

Sensitive  and   insensitive   1926-39,  index;  comment,  sulphur,  brick, 

wheat;  chart  1  and  table  by  months 20-24,252 

PRICE  SPREADS: 

Commodity  types;  manufactured  v.  agricultural  goods 11 


INDEX  4]^5 

PRICE  STRUCTURES:  Page 

Basing-point:  products  subject  to 345 

Flexible  and/or  inflexible.  {See  PRICE  RIGIDITY.) 

Freight  equalization:  Products  subject  to 344 

Geographic  price  structures;  part  II,  by  Saul  Nelson  and  William  C. 

French,  Jr 267 

Geographic,  type  analysis 343 

Rigid  and/or  nonrigid.     (-See  PRICE  RIGIDITY.) 
Sensitive  and/or  insensitive.     {See  PRICE  RIGIDITY.) 
Uniform  delivered  price: 

Products  subject  to 343 

Zone  delivered  pl-ice: 

Products  subject  to 344 

PRICE  TRENDS: 

Types  of  movement  casual,  seasonal,  cyclical,  and  secular,  role  of  each.  _         20 
PRICE  WARS: 

Causes 8,  56,  91 

Salt  industry 100,  297 

PRODUCTION: 

Price  dispersion  and;  index  industrial  production  and  reciprocals  of 
price  dispersion,  wholesale  prices  of  30  basic  commodities,  1926-39; 

comment,  chart  6  and  table  (by  months) 43-44,  257 

Price  dispersion  and;  indexes,  chart  7  (1928-40)  and  table  (1928-39), 

by  months . 46,  258 

Price  relationship 37 

PUMPS:  Geographic  price  structure 335 

PURCHASING   POWER,     FARMER.      {See    FARM    PURCHASING 

POWER.) 
RADIOS: 

Ownership  by  family  income  groups,  1935-36;  charts  23  and  24  and 

table.... 128-29,264 

Price  lining 249 

Statistics : 

1929-37,  average  retail  value  and  sales,  1929,  1932,  1937_. 112 

RADIO  TUBES:  Geographic  price  structure,  receiving  tubes 333 

RANGE  AND  HOT  PLATE  INDUSTRIES: 

Average  expenditure  per  income  level  by  wage  earner  and  clerical 

worker  families;  table  13 130 

Expenditures  by  wage  earner  and  clerical  worker  families  for  electric 

stoves  and  hot  plates ;  amount  and  percent  of  family  income ;  table  24^       1 64 

Geographic  price  structure 337 

Market  saturation.     {See  MARKET  SATURATION.) 
Sales.     (See  MARKET  SATURATION.) 
Statistics: 

1925-38.     Market  saturation;  percentage  of  wired  homes  owning 

ranges;  table  11 118 

1927-38.     Market   saturation,    percent,    and    number   of   sales; 

chart  16 11^ 

1927-38.     Number  sold  and  retail  value;  average  realization  at 

retail  and  wholesale  price  index;  chart  15  and  table 116,  262 

1929-37.     Average   retail   value   and   sales,    1929,    1932,    1937; 

table  10 - 112 

RAYON,  wholesale  price  index,   1926-39;  comment,  chart  2  and  table 

(by  months) 23,25,253 

RECESSION  AND  RECOVERY.     {See  also  BUSINESS  CYCLE.) 

Commoditv  price  response  variation,  1929-33  depression 11,  16,  23,  40 

1933-37  recession 16 

Rigid  versus  flexible  price  structure  upon  economy  during  periods  of. .         12 

Sales  policy  response,  1937-38  recession,  refrigerator  industry 137 

REFRIGERATORS,  ELECTRIC: 

Average  expenditure  per  income  level  by  wage  earner  and  clerical 

worker  families;  table  13 . 130^ 

Concentration,  production  first  four  companies,  1937;  percent  of  total, 

total  production,  number  of  companies;  table  22 163 

Distributive  margin:  typical  standard  brand  sales  organization;  mass 

distributor -  —  -.       145 


416  INDEX 

KEFRIGERATORS,  ELECTRIC— Continued. 

Durability  of  electric  refrigerators:  life  expectancy  in  years  by  year     Page 

of  manufacture,  1920-38 149 

Expenditures  by  wage  earner  and  clerical  worker  families  for  electric 

refrigerators,  average  amount  and  percent;  table  24 164 

Geographic  price  structure 336 

"Leader"  selling 136,  142 

Market  expansion  sales  effort 138 

Market  sq,turation.     {See  MARKET  SATURATION.) 

Ownership  by  family  income  groups,  1935-36;  charts  17  and   18  and 

table 122-123,263 

Price  lining 249 

Price  structure,  1940  change 154 

Prices,  1938,  table  21,  list,  by  companies 162 

Prices,  1939  and   1940,  retail  published  list  prices;  table  20 155-156 

Reconditioning  plans,  Crosley  and  Philadelphia 152-153 

Replacement  sales,  ratio,  1929-38;  table  18 148 

Sales.     {See  MARKET  SATURATION.) 

Seasonal  sales  promotion 137 

Statistics: 

1925-38.     Market  saturation;  percentage  of  wired  homes  owning 

electric  refrigerators;  table   11 118 

1927-38.     Market     saturation,    percent;     sales     in     thousands; 

clmrt  16 119 

1927-38.     Number  sold  and  retail  value,  realization  and  whole- 
sale price  (1932-38);  chart  12  and  table 113,261 

1928-37.     Distributive  margin:  Average  factory  price,  retail  price; 

actual  and  percent  margin;  table  14 144 

1928-37.     Factory  price;  comment,  chart  3  and  table 26-27,  255 

1929-37.     Average   retail    value   and   sales,    1929,    1932,    1937; 

table  10 . - .-.       112 

1929  and  1937-8.     Market  saturation,  percent  of  wired  homes, 
1929   and    1937;   percent   change   in   sales,    1929   to   average 

1932-33  and  1937-38;  table  11 118 

"Stripped"    lines 142 

Trade-in  allowance  statistics,  1933-38,  cash  values;  table  23 163 

REPLACEMENT   MARKET: 

Automobile  industry,  outstanding  example  of  shift  from  original  to 

replacement  market 148 

Obsolescence: 

Automobiles,     electric     refrigerators,     washing    machines,     and 

vacuum  cleaners 149-150 

Trade-in  allowance: 

Automobiles,    refrigerators,    washing    machines,    and    vacuum 

cleaners 150 

Cash  value  on  trade-ins:  Electric  refrigerators  and  automobiles, 

1933-38;  table  23 163 

RESALE  PRICE  MAINTENANCE.     {See  PRICE  MAINTENANCE.) 

RICE:  Geographic  price  structure 298 

ROAD  MACHINERY:  Geographic  price  structure 336 

ROBINSON-PATMAN   ACT 62 

Desirability  questionable  under  certain  conditions 14 

Effect  on  system  of  distributid/n 52 

ROOFING:  Geographic  price  structure 313 

RURAL  ELECTRIFICATION  ADMINISTRATION:  Surveyte  on  extent 

of  use  of  electrical  appliances  in  Administration  territory 160 

SALES:  Market  saturation  and  {See  MARKET  SATURATION). 

"lALES  STRATEGY:  Electrical  household  equipment 131 

Expert  buyer  versus  untrained  consumer  _    68 

"Leader"  selling - 136 

Refrigerator  industry 142 

Nonprice  competition . 56 

Replacement  market: 

Electtical  equipment  industry 148 

Seasonal  modifications: 

Refrigerator  industry 137 

Set-back  method  (n.) --- -       142 


INDEX  417 

SALES  STRATEGY:  Electrical  household  equipment— Continued. 

"Stripped"  lines:  Page 

Refrigerator  industry 142 

Techniques 5 

Types  of  concessions  to  influepce  sales  as  dealt  with  by  codes 94 

■SALT: 

Geographic  price  structure 296 

Prices,  nominal  versus  actual 100 

SCRAP  METAL:  Geographic  price  structure. 340 

SEASONALITY:  Price  movement 20-22 

Sales  policy: 

Refrigerator  industry 137 

SECULAR  PRICE  TRENDS:  Significance 20 

SIMONS,  PROF.  HENRY  C:  Positive  program  for  laissezf  aire;  cited(n.)-  17 
SMALL  VERSUS  LARGE  ENTERPRISES:  Ba^es  of  competition,  viz, 

quality  service,  prestige,  large;  price  inducement  small 91 

SOUTHERN  PINE:  Geographic  price  structure 309 

SOYBEAN  OIL :  Geographic  price  structure 295 

■SPENDING :  Price  relationship 42 

STANDARD  PRODUCTS:  Differentiated  products  versus 7 

STEEL  INDUSTRY :  Geographic  price  structure 305 

■STEVENSON,  .CHARLES  R.:  Price  control  and  the  allotment  of  busi- 
ness; cited  (n.) ._. 61 

SUGAR :  Geographic  price  structure 295 

SULFUR:  Wholesale  price  index;  chart  1  and  table  (by  months),  1926-39.  24,  252 
SULFURIC  ACID: 
Price  data: 

Quoted  price  and  price  paid  by  large  buyer  1928-37;  table  99 99 

TECHNOLOGICAL  CHANGE: 

Effect  on  price  rigidity .. 11 

Stimulated  by  nonprice  competition 56 

TEMPORARY  NATIONAL    ECONOMIC    COMMITTEE:    Consumer 

brand  preference  questionnaire 78 

THOMAS,  JOHN  F.:  Varying  functions  in  distribution;  cited  (n) 115 

THORP,  WILLARD  L.,  AND  A.  H.  CAESAR:  Open  price  filing  in  the 

electrical  manufacturing  industry ;  cited  (n.) 333 

AND  ERNEST  A.  TUPPER:  Potash  industry;  cited  (n.) 325-326 

TIRE  MANUFACTURING  INDUSTRY: 

Small  versus  large  manufacturers;  conflict  over  price  and/or  nonprice 

competition 93 

Wholesale  price,  and  average  life  of  automobile  tires,  1913-38;  chart 

Sand  table . 65,258 

TOBACCO :  Geographic  price  structure 304 

TOILETRIES:  Geograiphic  price  structure 323 

TOOLS,  STEEL:  Geographic  price  structure 308 

TOULMIN,  H.  A.,  JR.:  Patents  and  the  public  interest;  cited  (n.) 139 

TRADE  ASSOCIATIONS: 

Anti-price-cutting  campaigns  of 61 

Price  competition  propaganda 8 

Price  cutting  undesirability  propaganda 36 

TRADE-MARKS.     {See  BRANDS  AND  TRADE-MARKS.) 

TRANSPORTATION  COSTS:  Freight-biU  data  inadequate 271 

TUCKER,  RUFUS  S.:  Sensitive  and  administered  prices;  cited  (n.) 18 

TURBINES:  Geographic  price  structure 335 

TURPENTINE:  Geographic  price  structure 310 

TWENTIETH   CENTURY  FUND:  Does  distribution  cost  too  much; 

cited  (n.) 271 

TWINE:  Geographic  price  structure 302 

TYPEWRITERS:  Geographic  price  structure 336 

UNFAIR  PRACTICES  ACT: 

Desirability  questionable  under  certain  conditions 14 

Effect  on  system  of  distribution 52 

Use  of  by  trade  associations  for  price-control  vehicle 62 

UNIFORM  DELIVERED  PRICING 282 


418  INDEX 

UNITED  STATES  BUREAU  OF  FOREIGN  AND  DOMESTIC  COM-     ^*^* 
•MERGE: 

Domestic  Commerce  Series  No.  73.     Merchandising  requirements  of 

the  drug  store  package;  cited  (n.) 355 

Domestic  Commerce  Series  No.  90.     Cost,  sales,  and  profits  in  the 

retail  drug  trade ;  cited  (n.) SS^ 

UNITED  STATES  HOUSE  COMMITTEE  ON  COINAGE,  WEIGHTS 
AND  MEASURES:  Hearings  on  H.  R.  6964,  Standard  Metal  Con- 
tainer Act  of  1937,  1938;  cited  (n.) 77 

VACUUM  CLEANER  INDUSTRY: 

Average  expenditure  per  income  level,  by  wage-earner  and  clerical- 
worker  famiUes;  table  13 130 

Concentration,    production   first   four   companies,   percent   of   total, 

total  production,  number  of  companies,  1937;  table  22 leS' 

Distributive  margin 145 

Expenditures  by  wage-earner  and  clerical- worker  families  for  vacuum 

cleaners;  amount  and  percent  of  family  income;  table  24 164 

Geographic  price  structure 337 

Market  saturation.     {See  MARKET  SATURATION.) 

Ownership  of  cleaners  by  family  income  groups,  1935-36;  charts  21 

and  22  and  table - 126-27,  26» 

Price  living 249^ 

Reconditioning  exchanges 15S 

Sales.     (See  MARKET  SATURATION.) 

Sales  techniques 140 

Statistics: 

1925-38.   Market  saturation;  percentage  of  wired  homes  owning 

vacuum  cleaners;  table  11 118 

1927-38.   Market  saturation,  percent,  and  number  of  sales;  chart 

16 119' 

1927-38.  Number  sold  and  retail  value;  average  realization  at 

retail  and  wholesale  price  index;  chart  14  and  table 115,  261 

1929-37.  Average  retail  value  and  sales,  1929,  1932,  1937 112 

1929-38.   Market  saturation,  percent  of  wired  homes,  1929  and 
1937-38;  percent  change  in  sales,  1929  to  average  1932-33  and 

1937-38;  table  11 118 

VEGETABLE  OILS:  Geographic  price  structure 294 

VEGETABLES :  Geographic  price  structure 292 

WARE,  CAROLINE  F.,  AND  GARDINER  C.  MEANS:  Modern  econ- 
omy in  action;  cited  (n.) 18 

WASHING-MACHINE  INDUSTRY: 

Average  expenditure  per  income  level,  by  wage-earner  and  clerical- 
worker  families;  table  13 130 

Concentration,  production,  first  four  companies,  percent  total,  total 

production,  number  of  companies,  1937;  table  22 163: 

Distributive  margin 144,  145 

Expenditures  by  wage-earner  and  clerical-worker  families  for  washing 

machines;  average  amount  and  percent  family  income;  table  24 164 

Geographic  price  structure 337 

"Leader"  selling 142 

Market  saturation.     (See  MARKET  SATURATION.) 
WASHING  MACHINES: 

Ownership    by   family-income   groups,    1935-36;    charts    19-20  and 

table 124-125,263 

Price   lining .^ 249 

Replacement  sales  ratio ' 149 

Sales.     (See  MARKET  SATURATION.) 

Sales  techniques 139' 

Statistics : 

1925-38.   Market  saturation;  percentage  of  wired  homes  owning 

electric  washing  machines;  table  11 118 

1927-38.  Number  sold  and  retail  value;    wholesale   price  -and 

realization;  chart  13  and  table 114,  261 

1927-38.  Market   saturation,    percent,    and    number    of    sales; 
chart  16 - 119 


INDEX 


419 


WASHING  MACHINES— Continued. 

Statistics — Continued.  Page" 

1929-37.  Average  retail  value  and  sales,  1929,  1932,  1937 112 

1929-38.   Market  saturation,  percent  of  wired  homes,   1929,  and 
1937-38;  percent  change  in  sales,  1929  to  average  1932-33  and 

1937-38:  table  11 US 

WEARING  APPAREL  INDUSTRY: 

Cash  discount 250 

Geographic  price  structure 301 

Price  lining: 

Consumer  problems  simplified ^ 102 

Wholesale  market 242 

WHEAT: 

Geographic  price  structure 289 

Wholesale  price  index;  chart  1  and  table  (by  months),  1926-39 24,  252 

WINDOW  GLASS:  Geographic  price  structure 315 

WORK  PROJECTS  ADMINISTRATION:  Price  dispersion  and  indus- 
trial activity,  1928-1938;  cited  (n.) 45 

ZINC:  Geographic  price  structure 338 

ZONE  PRICING: 

Chemicals 31 9-323 

Products  subject  to 344 

o 


•«=-lf 


g-SX,  „2  6