Skip to main content

Full text of "Investigation of concentration of economic power; monograph no. 1[-43]"

See other formats


^^3d  SeMfon^^l        SENATE  COMMITTEE  PRINT 

INVESTIGATION  OF  CONCENTRATION 
OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


TEMPORARY  NATIONAL  ECONOMIC 
COMMITTEE 

A  STUDY  MADE  UNDER  THE  AUSPICES  OF  THE  DEPART- 
MENT OF  COMMERCE  AND  THE  FEDERAL  TRADE  COM- 
MISSION  FOR   THE  TEMPORARY   NATIONAL   ECONOMIC 
COMMITTEE.SEVENTY-SIXTH  CONGRESS, THIRD  SESSION, 
PURSUANT  TO  PUBLIC  RESOLUTION  NO.   113  (SEVENTY- 
FIFTH    CONGRESS),    AUTHORIZING    AND    DIRECTING    A 
SELECT  COMMITTEE  TO  MAKE  A  FULL  AND  COMPLETE 
STUDY   AND    INVESTIGATION    WITH    RESPECT   TO   THE 
CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  IN,  AND 
FINANCIAL  CONTROL  OVER,  PRODUCTION. AND 
DISTRIBUTION  OF  GOODS  AND  SERVICES 


MONOGRAPH  No.  6 

EXPORT  PRICES  AND  EXPORT  CARTELS 

(WEBB-POMERENE  ASSOCIATIONS) 


Printed  for  the  use  of  the 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee 


UNITED  STATES 

GOVERNMENT  PRINTING  OFFICE 

WASHINGTON  :  1941 


TEMPORARY  NATIONAL  ECONOMIC   COMMITTEE 
(Created  pursuant  to  Public  Res.  113.  75th  Cong.) 

.JOSEPH  C.  O'MAHONEY,  Senator  from  Wyoming,  Chairman 

HATTON  W.  SUMNERS,  Representative  from  Texas,  Vice  Chairman 

WILLIAM  H.  KING,  Senator  from  Utah 

WALLACE  H.  WHITE,  Jr.,  Senator  from  Maine 

CLYDE  WILLIAMS,  Representative  from  Missouri 

B.  CARROLL  REECE,  Representative  from  Tennessee 

THURMAN  W.  ARNOLD,  Assistant  Attorney  General 

•WENDELL  BERGE,  Special  Assistant  to  the  Attorney  General 

Representing  the  Department  of  Justice 

JEROME  N.  FRANK.  Chairman 

•SUMNER  T.  PIKE,  Commissioner 

Representing  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission 

CARLAND  S.  FERGUSON,  Commissioner 

•EWIN  L.  DAVIS,  Chairman 

Representing  the  Federal  Trade  Commission 

ISADOR  LUBIN,  Commissioner  of  Labor  Statistics 

•A.  FORD  HINRICHS,  Chief  Economist,  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics 

Representing  the  Department  of  Labor 

JOSEPH  J.  O'CONNELL,  Jr.,  Special  Assistant  to  the  General  Counsel 

•CHARLES  L.  KADES,  Special  Assistant  to  the  General  Counsel 

B«presenting  the  Department  of  the  Treasury 


Representing  the  Department  of  Commerce 

LEON  HENDERSON,  Economic  Coordinator 

DEWEY  ANDERSON,  Executive  Secretary 

THEODORE  J.  KBBPS,  Economic  Adviser 


^Alternates. 


MONOOKAPH  No.   6 

EXPORT  PRICES  AND  EXPORT  CARTELS    (WEBB-POMERENB 
ASSOCIATIONS) 

JtflLTON  GILBESIT  AND  PATJL  D.  DICKENS 

DEIPARTMENT  OP  COMMiaiCE 

AND  MEaiBERS  OF  THE  STAFF  OF  THB 

FEDERAL  TBADE  COMMIS6TON 

u 


ACKNOWLEDGMENT 


The  various  parts  of  this  monograph  were  written  by 

MILTON  GILBERT 

Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce 
Depa/rtment  of  Commerce 

PAUL  D.  DICKENS 

Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce 
Department  of  Commerce 

and  by 
members  of  the  staff  of  the 

FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION 

The  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  is  greatly  indebted 
to  these  authors  for  this  contribution  to  the  literature  of  the  subject 
under  review. 

The  status  of  the  materials  in  this  volume  is  precisely  the  same  as 
that  of  other  carefully  prepared  testimony  when  given  hy  individu^ 
witnesses;  it  is  information  submitted  for  Committee  deliberation. 
No  matter  what  the  official  capacity  of  the  witness  or  author  may  6ej 
the  publication  of  his  testirrwny.^  report.,  or  rkonograph  by  the  Com- 
mittee in  no  way  signifies  nor  implies  assent  to^  or  approval  of,  any  of 
the- facts.,  opinions^  or  recom/mendations.^  nor  acceptam.ce  thereof  in 
whole  or  in  part  by  the  members  of  the  Temporary  National  Economic 
Committee,  individually  or  collectively.  Sole  and  undivided  respon- 
sibility for  every  statement  in  such  testi/mony^  reports,  or  monographs 
rests  entirely  upon  the  respective  authors. 

(Signed)     Joseph  C.  OMahonet, 
Chairman,  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee. 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


PSE« 

Letter  of  transmittal ix 

Foreword — xiii 

PARTI 

A    SAMPLE    STUDY    OF    DIFFERENCES    BETWEEN    DOMESTIC  AND 
EXPORT  PRICING  POLICY  OF  UNITED  STATES  CORPORATIONS 

CHAPTER  I  Page 

Statement  of  the  problem. 3 

The  suggestion  in  the  President's  monopoly  message 3 

Scope  and  limits  of  the  study 4 

Relation  of  different  export  and  domestic  prices  to  the  monopoly 

problem 4 

CHAPTER    II 

Earlier  Studies  of  Export  Pricing  Policies 7 

CHAPTER    III 

Scope  of  the  Field  Study 12 

CHAPTER    IV 

Problems  Involved  in  Comparing  Domestic  and  Export  Prices 16 

CHAPTER   V 

Comparison  of  Export  and  Domestic  Price  Policies 29 

Group  I.  Cases  of  higher  export  than  domestic  prices 31 

Group  II.  Cases  of  export  prices  equal  to  domestic  prices 36 

Group  III.  Cases  of  lower  export  than  domestic  prices 44 

CHAPTER    VI 

The  Economic  Factors  Determining  Export  Price  Policy 63 

Export  prices  higher  than  domestic  prices 63 

Volume  of  trade  at  higher  than  domestic  prices 67 

Export  prices  equal  to  domestic  prices 68 

Export  prices  lower  than  domestic  prices 70 

1.  Why  price  concessions  are  granted 70 

2.  Factors  in  foreign  markets  which  necessitate  lower  export 

prices 72 

3.  Why  domestic  prices  are  higher 74 

(a)   Monopoly  aspects  of  the  problem 74 

(6)  The  influence  of  tariffs ^ 81 

(c)  The  selling  problem  in  the  domestic  and  foreign  markets.  82 

4.  Other  factors  influencing  export  price  policy 84 

CHAPTEB  VII 

Oonclusions 91 

PART  II 
DIRECT  FOREIGN  INVESTMENTS  IN  AMERICAN  INDUSTRY,  1937 

Page 

Foreword 97 

Introductory. 99 

-    T 


VI  TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 

Page 

Foreign  Direct  Investments  in  the  United  States  and  Tlieir  Significance..  100 

Industrial  distribution 101 

Geographic  distribution 104 

Foreign  control  of  United  States  production 105 

Concentration  of  assets  and  investment 108 

Conclusion HO 

PART  III 

REPORT  OF  THE  FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION  ON  THE  OPERATION 
OF  THE  EXPORT  TRADE  ACT  (WEBB-POMERENE  LAW)  1918-40 

Page 

Background 113 

Report  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  on  cooperation  in  American 

export  trade,  1916 113 

Debates  in  Congress,  hearings,  and  committee  reports 118 

The  law  as  passed  on  April  10,1918 119 

Administration  of  the  Law 123 

1918-27— The  Export  Trade  Division 123 

Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  1,  1919 123 

Proposed  amendment  to  the  law,  1921 123 

The  Silver  letter,  1924 123 

Proposed  amendment  to  permit  import  combines,  introduced  in  1924 

(rejected  in  1928) .-  123 

1927-40— The  Export  Trade  Section 129 

Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  2,  1935 129 

Pacific  Forest  Industries,  recommendations,  1940 129 

Annual  reports  of  the.  Commission,   1916-39 — publicity  statements 

issued  concerning  the  law 131 

Procedure  under  the  Act . ■ 132 

Products  Exported— Value  of  Exports,  1920-38 133 

Number  of  Associations  and  of  Member  Companies 135 

Types  of  Organization ; 136 

Functions  of  the  Groups 138 

Serving  as  export  sales  agent  for  the  members 138 

Purchasing  the  members'  products  for  resale  in  foreign  markets 138 

Employing  agents  and  directing  agents  of  the  members — promoting 

conferences  and  agreements  in  export  trade 139 

Exploitation  of  members'  products  abroad 139 

Agreement  upon  terms  and  sales  policies  in  export  trade 140 

Allocation  of  the  export  business 141 

Standardization  of  products  exported — inspection  and  claims  service.  141 
Arranging  for  insurance,  freight  rates,  cargo  space,  shipping  dates, 

and  storage 142 

Collecting  and  disseminating  trade  information  as  to  market  condi- 
tions abroad,  credits,  exchange,  shipping  regulations,  foreign  laws.  142 

Advantages  Derived  by  Cooperative  Effort 143 

Obstacles  Met  by  Export  Associations — Reasons  for  Dissolution  of  Some 

of  the  Groups 146 

Future  of  the  Webb-Pomerene  Law 146 

Appendix — Exhibits : 

1 .  Text  of  the  Export  Trade  Act  (Webb-Pomerene  law) 149 

2.  List  of  associations  filing  papers  with  the  Federal  Trade  Commis- 

sion, February  1940 152 

3.  List  of  associations  formed  under  the  act,  1918-39,  with  names  of 

members  and  the  years  in  which  they  held  membership — also 
notes  on  operation  of  each  association,  and  if  dissolved,  reasons 

for  dissolution 154 

4.  First  report  form 234 

5.  Annual  report  form 237 

6.  Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  1,  1919 240 

7.  Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  2,  1935 251 

8.  Excerpts  from  annual  report  of  the  Commission,  1937 261 

9.  Excerpts  from  annual  report  of  the  Commission,  1938 272 

10.  Excerpts  from  annual  report  of  the  Commission,  1939 284 

1 1 .  Selected  list  of  references  on  the  Export  Trade  Act 297 

Index _ _  301 


SCHEDULE  OF  TABLES 


PART  I 

Page 
1.  Distribution  of  76  cases  among  3  groups  and  13  types  of  price  policies.         31 

PART   II 

1.  Estimate  of  Foreign  investments  in  the  United  States,  end  of  1937 99 

2.  Foreign  direct  investments  in  the  United  States,  by  industries,  1937 100 

3.  Foreign  direct  investments  in  United  States,  by  principal  countries  and 

industries,  1937 103 

4.  Foreign  direct  investments  in  the  United  States,  by  countries,  1937 105 

5.  Study  of  international  affiliations  of  American  industry  based  on  census 

of  manufactures,  1937 106 

6.  Financial  structure  of  foreign  direct  investments  in  the  United  States, 

by  industrial  groups  and  by  geographic  areas,  end  of  1937 109 

vn 


LETTER  OF  TRANSMITTAL 


o 

August  23,  1940. 
The  Honorable  Senator  Joseph  C.  O'Mahonet, 

Chairman^  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee^ 
Washington^  D.  G. 

Mt  Dear  Senator:  I  have  the  honor  to  transmit  herewith  a  study 
on  some  phases  of  Export  Prices  and  Export  Cartels  ( Webb-Pomerene 
Associations).  In  this  volume  there  are  gathered  together  three  re- 
ports, two  by  the  Department  of  Commerce  and  one  by  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission,  When  these  were  submitted  to  the  Subcommittee 
on  Printing  and  Review  of  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Com- 
mittee, it  approved  them  for  printing  with  the  stipulation  that  they 
be  combined  into  one  volume,  prefaced  by  an  explanatory  introductory 
statement,  which  I  submit  herewith. 

The  field  of  foreign  trade  has  traditionally  been  beset  with  contro- 
versies and  arguments  about  tariffs,  reciprocal  trade  agreements,  in- 
ternational prices,  monopolistic  exchange  controls,  exchange  dump- 
ing, quotas,  barter  arrangements,  long-term  and  short-term  loans,  in- 
ternational combines,  and  cartels.  Businesses  on  occasion  do  abroad 
what  they  would  not  or  could  not  do  at  home.  Foreign  trade  is  re- 
garded by  some  as  the  happy  hunting  ground  of  gigantic  international 
understandings,  political  controls,  economic  imperialism,  and  ruthless 
■competitive  warfare  with  success  a  matter  of  national  prestige.  These 
studies  make  intensive  probings  into  but  one  or  two  corners  of  the  area 
ordinarily  encompassed  by  foreign  trade.  But  in  those  corners  they 
show  interesting  action  patterns  of  concentration  of  economic  power 
at  work. 

Part  I  is  a  study  written  by  Dr.  Milton  Gilbert  of  the  Department 
of  Commerce  entitled  "A  Sample  Study  of  Differences  Between  Do- 
mestic and  Export  Pricing  Policy  of  the  United  States  Corporations." 
It  explores  a  most  difficult  problem  for  it  seeks  not  only  to  distinguish 
domestic  prices  from  export  prices  but  to  determine  whether  such 
differences  as  exist  reveal  the  presence  or  absence  in  one  form  or  other 
of  economic  control. 

This  task  is  the  most  difficult  in  most  instances  because  there  is  no 
single  domestic  priee.  There  are  hosts  of  domestic  prices.  The  New 
York  price,  for  example,  even  of  such  an  article  as  butter  or  flour 
■differs  considerably  from  the  price  in  Kansas  City  or  San  Francisco. 
There  are  many  reasons  for  divergences  of  prices  at  home  and  abroad, 
differences  in  no  way  related  to  the  presence  of  monopoly  or  of  con- 
centration of  economic  power,  for  all  prices  are  local  prices  subject  to 
local  variations  in  demand,  supply,  control,  taxes,  and  governmental 
regulation.  It  is  only  in  the  peculiar  instance  when  the  domestic  price 
is  high,  completely  inflexible  and  completely  under  control  and  the 
foreign  price  low,  highly  flexible,  and  uncontrolled  that  one  can  infer 

iz. 


X  LETTER  OF  TRANSMITTAL 

the  presence  of  monopoly  solely  from  a  study  of  differences  in  price 

honfl-Vior 

When,  however,  there  is  incompletely  monopolistic  control  in  some 
markets' at  home  with  a  great  deal  of  competition  in  others  coupled' 
with  partial  control  in  foreign  markets,  some  being  exclusively  dom- 
inated while  in  others  a  considerable  amount  of  competition  exists,  the 
relationship  between  any  given  domestic  price  and  the  price  in  those 
few  foreign  markets  to  which  a  corporation  may  have  obtained  access, 
is  likely  not  to  show  any  substantial  regularity.^ 

Tlie  converse  of  the  proposition  stated  above  is  likevvnse  true.  One 
cannot  infer,  for  example,  that  competition  is  present  when  the  price 
in  a  foreign  market  is  as  high  or  even  higher  than  in  the  domestic  mar- 
ket. In  certain  small  countries  a  domestic  corporation  may  readily 
liave  a  monopoly  while  suffering  competition  in  the  particular  domes- 
tic market  selected  by  the  sample  study  for  price  comparison.  In 
short,  to  come  to  any  conclusion  merely  on  the  basis  of  differences  in 
price  is  unwarranted.  Most  of  the  ready  inferences  that  monopolistic 
control  does  not  exist  because  of  variability  in  price  pattern  are 
unjustified. 

The  last  two  studies  constituting  parts  II  and  III  of  this  volume  deal 
with  the  groups  that  carry  on  foreign  trade,  and  in  particular  the  form 
of  their  organization.  Part  II,  entitled  "Direct  Foreign  Investments 
in  American  Industry,  1937,"  represents  a  study  made  by  Mr.  Paul  D. 
Dickens,  of  the  Department  of  Commerce,  analyzing  the  extent  to 
which  foreign-owned  corporations  control  production  in  the  United 
States.  Part  III,  entitled  "Operation  of  Export  Trade  Act  (Webb- 
Pomerene  law),  1918-1940,"  is  a  study  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commis- 
sion indicating  how  American  corporations  have  united  to  penetrate 
the  foreign  market.  Both  studies  give  a  limited  insight  into  the  op- 
eration of  combines  and  cartels  in  our  export  and  import  trade. 

The  vicissitudes  of  Webb-Pomerene  associations,  particularly  as 
illustrated  in  the  copper  industry,  Avere  studied  in  detail  by  the  Tem- 
I^orary  National  Economic  Committee  in  its  hearings  on  Cartels  at 
Home  and  Abroad.  Organized  originally  as  The  Copper  Export 
Association,  later  called  Copper  Exporters,  Inc.,  these  associations, 
according  to  Dr.  Rudolph  Callman,  well-known  expert  on  cartels  and 
author  of  a  volume  on  German  cartel  law  -  represent  types  of  cartels 
well  known  in  national  and  international  industry.  The  Copper  Ex- 
port Association  was  simply  a  joint  selling  agency.  It  would  be  called 
a  syndikat  in  the  German  cartel  law.  The  same  is  true  of  Copper 
Exporters,  Inc.,  although  the  situation  is  not  quite  so  clear  as  in  the 
Copper  Export  Association,  particularly  insofar  as  its  purpose,  instead 
of  being  that  of  mitigating  or  eliminating  competition  among  its 
members,  seemed  to  be  that  of  common  defense  against  speculators, 
who,  while  neither  producing  nor  consuming  copper,  were  believed  to 
be  responsible  for  artificial  and  harmful  fluctuations  in  copper  prices, 
particularly  in  the  London  metal  exchange.  But  the  evidence  showing 
that  the  major  effect  was  the  mitigation  of  competition  among  each 
other  was  so  convincing  that  I  feel  no  hesitancy  in  calling  Copper 
Exporters,  Inc.,  a  cartel.    And  may  I  add  that  it  was  thus  regarded 

^/J^Pf.**'^   theoretical   difficulties   of   Interpreting  differences   between    export   prices   and 
R??lnt    loo^foQn^  ^\^°*l?'"^  I   ?''^PS'   "I^xport.   Import,  Domestic  Prices  in  the  United 
5i^  •  \?^  .  ^u^'^^     /,^^  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  46,  p.  195  ff. 
Das  Deutsche  Kartellrecht,  Philo  Verlag,  Berlin,  1934      720  pp 


LETTER  OF  TRANSMITTAL  XI 

by  all  of  the  writers  on  cartel  problems  in  Europe.  Dr.  Robert  Lief- 
mann,  the  famous  German  expert,  in  his  book  entitled  "Cartels,  Com- 
bines, and  Trusts"  (London,  1928)  goes  so  far  as  to  say  (p.  60)  that 
Copper  Exporters,  Inc.,  was  ''a  ckar  case  of  export  cartels  deliberately 
fostered  by  the  Government  of  the  U.  S.  A.  to  the  detriment  of  the 
European  consumer," 

The  American  public  may  be  surprised,  if  not  annoyed,  by  such  a 
statement.  But  in  European  opinion  and  experience  cartels  that 
engage  in  international  trade  are  generally  assumed  to  be  fostered  by 
their  governments  because  cartels  are  frequently  merely  another  means 
of  international  trade  policy. 

Moreover,  Copper  Exporters  Inc.,  is  an  association  authorized  by 
the  Government  under  the  Webb-Pomerene  Act,  which  according  to 
the  evidence  presented  in  these  hearings,  was  strongly  urged  upon 
Congress  and  the  Wilson  administration  by  influential  members  of 
the  copper  industry. 

I  hasten  to  add  that  in  European  cartel  literature  and  discussions 
all  associations  formed  under  the  Webb-Pomerene  Act  are  regarded 
as  export  cartels.^ 

As  is  brought  out  in  part  III  of  this  volume  such  association^  often 
control  100  percent  of  the  export  of  their  members.  Many  of  them 
no  longer  rely  on  agents  abroad,  but  have  substituted  well-qualified 
association  agents.  Sales  in  many  instances  are  no  longer  made  on  a 
c.  i.  f.  basis  plus  letters  of  credit  set  up  at  home,  but  are  made  from 
warehouse  stocks  carried  abroad,  thus  enabling  export  sales  to  be 
allocated  quarterl}-. 

Moreover,  such  associations  often  amount  to  price  cartels,  the  estab- 
lishment of  prices  being  regarded  as  a  distinct  function  of  the  associ- 
ation, prices  depending  upon  economic  conditions  in  each  market 
compared  with  maximum  consuming  power  of  that  market  under 
normal  conditions.  In  other  words,  purchasing  power  or  "what  the 
traffic  will  bear"  is  an  important  factor  to  be  considered  with  respect 
to  maximum  sales.  Another  factor  is  competition.  Still  another 
is  quality  and  the  study  of  the  needs  of  important  consumers  in 
accordance  with  their  processes  of  manufacturing.  Thus  prices  neces- 
sarily fluctuate  in  different  parts  of  the  world,  being  controlled  by 
innumerable  conditions  both  political  and  economic.  In  some  in- 
stance's the  return  exceeds  domestic  levels.  In  others  it  is  about  the- 
same  and  in  others  it  will  occasionally  be  lower.  Consequently,  many 
associations  work  on  a  final  aA^erage  annual  price  on  behalf  of  the 
industry  which  return  is  distributed  equitably  in  proportion  to  each 
factory  shipment. 

To  some  extent  such  associations  become  sales  and  market 
cartels.  Business  in  many  of  them  is  divided  among  the  members  on 
a  quarterly  basis  which  is  adjusted  yearly  as  provided  for  in  member- 
ship agreements.  Individual  brands  may  be  shipped  in  the  same  size 
packages.  Individual  trade-marks  and  names  are  utilized  in  con- 
junction with  the  standardized  association  trade-mark.  Consolidation 
of  different  brands  in  a  single  shipment  is  a  common  occurrence  and 
is  utilized  by  the  association  in  accordance  with  its  own  discretion 

•  Investigation  of  Concentration  of  Economic  Power,  hearings  before  the  Temporary  Na- 
tional Economic  Committee,  Congress  of  the  United  States,  76th  Cong..  1st  sess.,  Cartels 
at  Home  and  Abroad. 


3^11  LETTER  OF  TRANSMITTAL 

either  from  shipments  arriving  from  different  plants  or  from  seaboard 
stocks.  In  some  instances  in  the  chemical  industry^  export  associations 
have  agreements  with  international  cartels  comprising  British,  conti- 
nental, and  other  foreign  manufacturers.  Certain  territorial  divisions 
are  required  as  exclusive  one  to  the  other  and  a  certain  division  of 
total  available  business  is  likewise  required,  the  latter  involving  per- 
centages in  some  joint  market  in  contrast  to  no  division  in  exclusive 

One  of  the  main  problems  that  arise  in  the  effective  operation  of 
Webb-Pomerene  associations  is  at  the  same  time  one  of  the  major 
problems  of  a  sales  cartel ;  that  is,  the  diversion  of  merchandise  through 
channels  of  export  outside  of  the  centralized  company  or  association. 
Independent  dealers  and  brokers  and  sometimes  large-scale  consumers 
cause  considerable  disturbances  in  prices  and  sales  by  covert  activity. 
Another  disturbing  factor  is  export  speculation  by  producers,  which 
may  not  only  be  detrimental  to  sustained  effort  of  the  cartel,  but  may 
at  times  cost  much  in  the  way  of  annoyance  and  reduction  of  prices 
in  certain  areas  abroad.  Fundamental  misrepresentation,  under-cover 
buying,  and  disregard  of  the  obligation  accepted  in  purchasing  also 
bring  about  diversion  unknown  to  the  association  members  of  domes- 
tic tonnage  into  export  channels.  There  has  consequently  been  some 
clamor  to  make  it  unlawful  for  any  firm  or  individual  to  export  or  to 
sell  for  export  any  commodities  of  a  Webb-Pomerene  corporation 
through  channels  other  than  those  controlled  and  maintained  by  such 
corporations.  This  would  make  if  impossible,  for  example,  for  pur- 
chasers allegedly  buying  for  export  to  attempt  to  move  the  material 
by  steamship  here  by  truck  and  resell  in  the  domestic  market. 

An  effective  cartel  or  efScient  conglomerate  of  economic  power 
naturally  always  attempts  to  get  as  profitable  a  rate  of  return  as  pos- 
sible on  all  business  done,  whether  in  the  domestic  or  in  the  foreign 
market.  Through  vigorous  organization  and  through  cooperation 
with  foreign  cartels,  an  industry  may  have  an  essentially  monopolistic 
hold  on  both  the  domestic  market  and  the  foreign  market.  Under 
such  conditions  with  prices  set  in  the  respective  markets  in  accordance 
with  "conditions"  and  "what  the  traffic  will  bear,"  differences  in  price 
have  little  meaning.  Certainly  they  do  not  show  competition  or  the 
absence  of  monopoly.  That  can  only  be  determined  by  studying  mar- 
ket organization  and  market  conditions,  commodity  by  commodity,  a 
study  which  has  not  been  made  in  this  volume. 

Respectfully  submitted. 

Theodore  J.  Keeps,  EconoTnic  Adviser. 


FOREWORD 


The  last  10  years  have  revolutionized  thinking  about  prices.  Both 
in  theory  and  research,  the  simple  "10  cents  for  an  orange"  concept 
of  price  has  given  way  to  a  recognition  that  price  is  a  complicated 
formula,  and  that  "the  law  of  single  price"  is  limited  to  very  small 
areas. 

For  many  years,  it  has  been  recognized  that  export  prices  may  suf- 
fer from  domestic  prices.  Many  countries  have  antidumping  laws  to 
prevent  foreigners  f i*om  selling  in  their  markets  too  cheaply.  In  some 
cases  legislation  has  also  been  directed  against  sale  abroad  at  levels 
below  those  at  which  the  products  are  made  available  to  domestic 
consumers.  Both  sets  of  laws  recognize  that  price  differences  may 
and  do  exist. 

The  present  study  is  directed  to  the  current  practices  of  American 
enterprises  selling  both  in  the  domestic  and  the  foreign  market.  In 
total,  76  cases  were  carefully  studied.  Under  an  assurance  of  confi- 
dential treatment,  the  business  executives  involved  were  most  cooper- 
ative in  presenting  the  picture  of  their  actual  price  practices.  While 
the  sample  provides  a  sufficient  cross  section  to  illustrate  the  various 
policies  which  are  to  be  found,  it  does  not  permit  an  exact  statistical 
measurement  of  the  importance  of  each  attitude  toward  the  foreign 
market. 

Probably  the  most  important  conclusion  is  that  the  foreign  and 
domestic  markets  are  frequently  not  sufficiently  unified  to  require 
identity  of  price.  And,  particularly  in  his  foreign-trade  efforts,  the 
businessman  appears  to  have  wide  scope  for  exercising  his  business 
judgment.  It  is  of  further  interest  to  note  the  case  where  the  busi- 
nessman cannot  clearly  declare  that  his  foreign  business  is  as  profit- 
able as  his  domestic.  But  it  is  evidently  extremely  difficult  to  with- 
draw from  a  market  as  long  as  the  future  permits  any  hope.  In 
many  cases,  the  export  business  is  not  regularly  tested  against  any 
tough  profit-or-loss  measure,  and  when  it  is,  does  not  show  satis- 
factory current  results. 

Above  all,  the  study  indicates  the  skill  required  for  effective  opera- 
tion in  foreign  trade.  All  the  problems  of  domestic  selling  are  pres- 
ent, with  certain  added  complications.  It  should  perhaps  be  noted 
that  in  the  face  of  these  complications,  our  Government  has  given 
much  less  aid  than  that  afforded  by  our  competitot-s  in  foreign  mar- 
kets. If  we  wish  to  keep  our  export  trade,  new  policies  may  be 
necessary. 

WiLLARD  L,  Thorp. 

XIII 


PART  I 

A  SAMPLE  STUDY  OF  DIFFERENCES  BETWEEN 

DOMESTIC  AND  EXPORT  PRICING  POLICY 

OF  UNITED  STATES  CORPORATIONS 

Prepared  by 
MILTON  GILBERT 

in  the 

Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce 
DEPARTMENT  OF  COMMERCE 


CHAPTER  I 
STATEMENT  OF  THE  PROBLEM 

THE  SUGGESTION  IN  THE  PKESIDENT's  MONOPOLY  MESSAGE 

In  his  message  to  Congress  which  resulted  in  the  establishment  of 
the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  President  Roosevelt 
reviewed  some  of  the  problems  facing  American  industry  and  offered 
for  consideration  some  recommendations  relative  to  the  strengthening^ 
and  enforcement  of  antitrust  laws.  Under  the  suggestions  for  im- 
provement of  antitrust  procedure  the  President  said : 

A  revision  of  the  existing  antitrust  laws  should  make  them  susceptible  of  pi-ac- 
tical  enforcement  by  casting  upon  those  charged  with  violations  the  burden  of 
proving  facts  peculiarly  within  their  knowledge.  Proof  by  the  Government  of 
identical  bids,  uniform  price  increases,  price  leadership,  higher  domestic  •  than 
export  prices,  or  other  specified  price  rigidities  might  be  accepted  as  prima  facie 
evidence  of  unlawful  actions.^ 

The  purpose  of  this  study  is  to  explore  the  possibilities  of  one  of 
these  suggestions — that  concerning  higher  domestic  than  export  prices. 
It  was  felt  that  the  ramifications  of  the  problem  would  only  be  re- 
vealed by  a  broad  study  which  would  offer  a  cross-section  picture  of  the 
export  pricing  policies  of  many  industries.  For  without  such  a  study^ 
the  perspective  required  for  the  formulation  of  practicable  and  con- 
vincing recommendations  to  the  Congress,  if  the  evidence  reveals  a 
need  for  such  action,  would  be  lacking. 

For  this  reason  the  Department  of  Commerce  has  undertaken  a 
study  of  business  practices  with  regard  to  pricing  for  export.  It  was 
considered  desirable  to  enlarge  the  scope  of  the  study  beyond  what  was 
specified  in  the  monopoly  message.  It  seemed  inadequate  merely  to 
uncover  instances  of  firms  in  industries  charged  with  monopolistic 
practices  selling  at  lower  prices  to  export  customers  than  to  domestic 
customers.  For  that  procedure  would  assume  the  basic  point  at  issue ; 
that  is,  that  the  ability  to  practice  price  discrimination  among  national 
markets  is  necessarily  an  attribute  of  monopoly  power.  Therefore,  a 
comparative  study  of  domestic  and  export  pricing  policies  of  a  repre- 
sentative sample  of  American  industry  has  been  attempted.  The 
study  embraces  firms  in  industries  with  many  independent  business 
units  and  firms  in  industries  with  few  business  units ;  large  firms  and 
small ;  some  firms  which  export  a  large  proportion  of  their  production 
and  otliers  which  export  only  a  small  percentage  of  their  output ;  firms 
with  branch  plants  abroad  and  firms  with  only  American  factories. 
The  emphasis  of  the  study  is  upon  a  comparison  of  domestic  and  ex- 
port prices  and  price  policy  and  the  reasons  or  explanations  for  any 
differences  which  may  come  to  light.  It  was  also  expected  that  some  of 
the  characteristics  of  the  price  system  under  which  American  business 
operates  would  be  revealed  by  the  investigation. 


IS.  Doc- '73,  T.oth  Cong.,  3d  sess.,   Strengthening  and  Enforcement  of  Antitrust  Laws, 
p.  7. 

:i5776'.t— 41— No.  6 2  3 


4  OONCEXNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

THE  SCOPE  AND  LIMITS  OF  THE  STUDY 

The  precise  nature  of  the  problem  to  which  this  study  is  devoted  may 
be  more  clearly  understood  by  noting  the  following  limitations  upon 
its  scope. 

(a)  It  is  concerned  only  with  goods  produced  in  the  United  States 
and  with  the  prices  in  the  American  market  at  which  those  goods  are 
sold  to  domestic  and  foreign  customers.  The  prices  of  similar  goods 
produced  by  foreign  branches  of  the  firm,  or  by  independent  foreign 
factories,  or  the  price  in  the  foreign  market  are  entirely  irrelevant. 
The  study  is  not  concerned  with  the  price  the  foreign  consumer  pays 
for  similar  goods  which  were  not  produced  in  the  United  States,  or 
with  the  prices  at  which  American  products  are  finally  offered  to  the 
foreign  -consumer  after  ocean  shipment,  payment  of  duty^  retailer's 
mark-up,  etc.,  have  been  added  to  the  manufacturer's  price.  It  is 
concerned  only  with  the  producer's  prices  to  similar  types  of  cus- 
tomers under  similar  conditions  of  sale.  Of  course,  there  are  many 
difficulties  involved  in  obtaining  truly  comparative  prices,  the  discus- 
sion of  which  is  postponed  to  a  later  section. 

(b)  The  field  survey  was  limited  to  manufactured  products;  non- 
processed  agricultural  or  mineral  products  are  not  considered  in  the 
report. 

(c)  The  differences  between  domestic  and  export  prices  which  are 
herein  considered  are  only  those  differences  which  are  the  result  of 
decisions  of  the  manufacturers.  Price  differences  which  arise  from 
domestic  governmental  policy  or  from  differences  in  distribution  serv- 
ice costs  not  controlled  by  the  manufacturer  are  evidently  irrelevant 
to  the  problem.  For  example,  a  Government  subsidy  on  exports,  an 
excise  tax  that  is  levied  on  production  for  domestic  consumption  but 
not  on  exports,  drawbacks  of  duty  paid  on  imported  raw  materials 
which  are  exported  aftesr  processing,  a  lower  inland  freight  rate  from 
factory  to  seaboard  on  export  shipments  than  on  domestic  business, 
niiglit  all  make  the  price  to  an  export  customer  lower  than  the  price 
to  a  domestic  customer.  But  as  these  factors  would  not  make  any 
difference  in  the  net  price  received  by  the  manufacturer,  they  are  not 
part  of  the  problem  under  consideration.  In  brief,  it  is  the  manufac- 
turer's net  prices  from  domestic  and  export  customers  which  are  to  be 
compared. 

THE  RELATION   OF    DIFFERENT  EXPORT   AND   DOMESTIC    PRICES    TO   THE 
MONOPOLY  PROBLEM 

A  brief  discussion  of  the  theory  of  dumping  has  been  injected  at 
this  time  to  show  why  a  study  of  the  practice  is  relevant  to  the 
problems  confronting  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee. 
The  most  careful  writers  on  the  subject  have  concluded  that  monopoly 
IS  a  prerequisite  for  dumping  and  it  is,  therefore,  pertinent  to  inquire 
whether  "higher  domestic  than  export  prices  might  be  accepted  as 
prima  facie  evidence  of  unlawful  actions."  The  many  important 
questions  revolving  around  the  meaning  of  monopoly  and  competition 
must  be  deferred  until  the  differences  between  domestic  and  export 
pricing  policies  have  been  surveyed. 

It  will  be  recognized  that  the  practice  referred  to  in  the  President's 
mo^snnre,  quoting  lower  prices  for  export  than  for  domestic  customers, 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  5 

is  what  is  generally  called  "dumping."  The  use  of  that  term  has  been 
avoided  as  far  as  possible  because,  both  in  its  legal  definition  and  gen- 
eral connotation,  it  includes  much  more  than  will  be  discussed  in  this 
study.  But  it  can  correctly  be  said  that  we  are  here  dealing  with  one 
type  of  dumping — that  which  rests  upon  the  sole  decision  of  the  pro- 
ducer or  seller.  This  type  of  dumping  may  be  defined  as  international 
price  discrimination  and  includes  differences  between  domestic  and 
export  prices  in  either  direction,  i.  e.,  higher  as  well  as  lower  export 
prices. 

Familiarity  with  economic  writing  on  this  type  of  dumping  would 
reveal  the  relation  between  dumping  and  the  monopoly  problem  and 
make  it  clear  why  evidence  of  the  practice  might  establish  a  presump- 
tion that  a  monopolistic  situation  exists.  Prof.  F.  W.  Taussig  has 
stated  the  relationship  as  follows : 

Sales  at  lower  prices  are  made  to  foreigners  not  only  sporadically,  but  for 
long  periods  and  systematically.  This  phenomenon  would  seem  to  be  ex- 
plicable only  on  the  ground  of  monopoly.  Where  there  are  competing 
producers,  no  one  of  them  will  steadily  accept  lower  prices  than  the  other. 
Each  will  be  desirous  of  selling  in  the  most  advantageous  market.  There 
will  be  dumping  of  the  sporadic  sort  only,  by  one  of  the  competitors  or  by 
several  of  them,  at  times  when  the  total  output  is  not  easily  carried  off  at 
remunerative  prices.  The  more  effective  is  competition,  the  more  standard- 
ized the  article,  the  less  likely  is  even  sporadic  dumping.  On  the  other  hand, 
the  more  removed  the  conditions  are  from  those  of  smooth-working  competi- 
tion— to  the  degree  that  there  is  influence  from  brands,  specialities,  quasi- 
monopoly,  complete  monopoly — the  more  is  there  likely  to  be  departure  from 
a  uniform  market  price,  and  the  more  likely  is  it  that  discrimination  and 
dumping  appear.^ 

Another  explanation  of  this  line  of  reasoning  is  given  in  the  widely 
known  monograph  on  dumping  by  Prof.  Jacob  Viner. 

In  the  ♦  *  *  summary  of  export  dumping,  it  was  made  apparent  that 
dumping  on  other  than  a  sporadic  basis  was  typically,  if  not  invariably, 
confined  to  monopolistic  producers'  combinations.  This  conforms  with  theo- 
retical expectations.  First,  dumping  is  most  likely  to  appear  to  be  profitable 
in  the  case  of  industries  using  large  plant  and  expensive,  machinery,  so 
that  the  fixed  charges  are  an  important  part  of  the  total  costs  of  production. 
For  such  industries  maintenance  of  output  at  near  maximum  capacity  is 
most  urgent  on  financial,  and  sometimes  on  technological,  grounds.  It  pays 
such  industries  to  accept  additional  orders  at  any  price  which  more  than 
covers  the  direct  costs,  if  these  orders  are  not  othewise  obtainable,  and  if 
full  production  cannot  be  maintained  without  them.  But  it  is  in  industries 
having  these  characteristics  that,  apart  from  natural  and  legal  monopolies, 
monopolistic  organization  is  most  likely  to  be  attempted,  mainly  In  order  to 
escape  the  danger  of  destructive  competition. 

Once  monopoly  control  has  been  achieved  in  the  domestic  market,  it  may 
pay,  if  domestic  orders  do  not  fully  occupy  the  productive  facilities,  to  bid  for 
orders  in  other  markets  at  prices  lower  than  those  exacted  at  home.  If 
cutthroat  competition  results  from  this  policy,  it  will  at  least  be  confined 
to  markets  in  which  the  dumping  organization  is  not  vitally  interested. 
The  mere  fact  of  monopoly  control  in  the  domestic  market  will  make  it 
probable  that  the  prices  exacted  In  that  market  will  be  above  the  competi- 
tive level  in  outside  markets,  and  that  foreign  orders  will  be  obtainable 
only  If  the  prices  quoted  to  prospective  foreign  purchasers  are  lower  than 
the  domestic  prices.  Monopoly  in  the  domestic  market  would  appear  for 
another  reason  to  be  essential  if  continued  dumping  is  to  be  profitable.  If 
there  is  competition  in  the  domestic  market,  the  concern  which  dumps  a 
portion  of  its  output  in  foreign  markets  in  order  tp  reduce  the  supply  and 
maintain  or  raise  the  prices  in  the  domestic  market  must  bear  by  itself  all 
the  sacrifice  involved  In  the  export  at  reduced  prices  and  must  share  with 


*P.  W.  Taussig,  Some  Aspects  of  the  Tariff  Question,  Cambridge,  1915,  p.  208. 


g  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

all  its  domestic  competitors  the  advantage  accruing  from  the  reduction  in  the- 
domestic  supply.  Under  these  circumstances  a  concern  will  have  as  much — 
or  nearly  as  much — to  gain  from  price  cutting  in  the  domestic  market  as 
from  export  dumping.  It  is  only  to  a  monopoly  that  export  dumping  has 
attractions  greater  than  those  of  moderate  domestic  price  cutting. 

It  is  on  grounds  such  a^  these  that  it  has  been  held  by  many  economists 
that  dumping  as  a  systematic  and  continued  practice  must  normally  be  con- 
fined to  monopolies.' 

The  essence  of  this  argument  is  that  unless  there  is  some  type  of 
monopolistic  restraint  in  the  domestic  market,  some  restriction  upon 
the  normally  competitive  pricing  mechanism,  it  will  not  be  to  the 
economic  advantage  of  any  single  producer  to  accept  the  loss  or  lower 
profit  involved  in  selling  to  foreign  customers  at  less  than  the  domestic 
market  price.  For  if  the  producer  must  make  a  price  concession  to- 
sell  his  total  output,  an  offer  of  a  lower  price  in  the  domestic  market 
would  be  just  as  effective  in  clearing  his  stocks  as  would  the  offering 
of  lower  prices  for  export  shipments.  But  when  some  monopolistic 
element  of  whatever  character  is  injected  into  the  domestic  market — 
some  factor  which  prevents  price  from  performing  its  usual  function 
in  a  competitive  market — then  excess  stocks  may  be  accumulated  or 
productive  capacity  remain  idle.  Under  such  circumstances  the  ex- 
port price  may  be  reduced  in  order  to  clear  excess  stocks  or  to  employ 
unused  capacity.  This  could  occur  whether  the  export  markets  were 
competitive  or  monopolistic. 

Thus,  the  existence  of  a  two-price  system  would  be  indicative  of 
some  impediment  to  competition  in  the  domestic  market.  A  situation 
that  would  conform  to  this  picture  is  that  of  a  group  of  producers 
having  a  tacit  or  explicit  agreement  with  regard  to  price  in  the  domes- 
tic market  but  no  such  agreement  with  foreign  producers  as  to  export 
prices.  The  monopoly  price  so  established  yields  an  abnormal  return 
in  the  sense  that  some  of  the  producers  would  accept  additional  busi- 
ness at  lower  prices  if  it  could  be  obtained  without  upsetting  the  ex- 
isting price  situation  in  the  domestic  market.  As  there  is  no  restric- 
tion on  competition  in  foreign  markets,  a  competitive  export  price  is 
established  which  is  lower  than  the  monopoly  price  in  the  domestic 
market.  Such  is  the  basic  type  of  situation  that  is  generally  conceived 
to  lead  to  the  practice  of  dumping.  The  primary  purpose  of  this 
study  is  to  see  if  the  facts  in  the  business  world  conform  to  this 
theoretical  picture. 

From  this  picture  it  can  be  seen  why  economists  have  insisted  that 
another  fundamental  factor,  in  addition  to  an  element  of  monopoly 
in  the  home  market,  is  required  to  make  dumping  possible.  This 
factor  is  protection  of  the  home  market,  for  in  order  for  the  domestic 
monopoly  to  be  effective,  the  competitively  priced  products  in  the 
foreign  markets,  originating  either  at  home  or  abroad,  must  be  pre- 
vented from  breaking  the  domestic  monopoly  price.  It  is  generally 
conceived  that  high  protective  tariffs  are  the  commonest  and  most 
effective  means  of  excluding  competitively  priced  goods  from  the 
home  market.  But  freight  costs,  if  they  are  large  in  proportion  to 
the  value  of  the  product,  may  be  equally  restrictive.  Besides,  the 
manufacturer  may  have  agreements  with  distributors,  even  with 
those  ni  the  foreign  market  restricting  them  from  reshipping  the 
goods  to  the  United  States.^ 

!  W°rJJ?r^i^'^^^V"P'?r^L'^,  ^^^^l^*"  *°  International  Trade.    Chicago,  1923.  pp.  94-95. 
p.  301     ^^^^'^'^'^'^   ^0°    Haberler,    The  Theory    of   International    Trade,    New   York,    1936, 


CHAPTER  II 
EARLIER  STUDIES  OF  EXPORT  PRICING  POLICIES 

There  is  considerable  evidence  that  for  many  years  American  indus- 
try has  sold  its  products  abroad  at  other  than  domestic  prices.  That 
evidence,  however,  is  not  very  satisfactory  in  revealing  the  extent  of 
the  practice,  the  magnitude  of  price  differentials,  or  the  economics 
of  the  problem.  While  a  few  official  inquiries  were  made,  the  informa- 
tion disclosed  is  not  sufficient  to  answer  the  questions  of  major  inter- 
est. But  as  to  the  mere  existence  of  price  differentials  for  some 
products  there  can  be  no  doubt.^ 

One  of  the  earliest  notices  of  exporting  at  lQ^^er  than  domestic  prices 
in  official  publications  was  made  in  regard/'to  the  steel  industry  and 
its  effect  upon  shipbuilding  in  a  monthly  statistical  bulletin  formerly 
issued  by  the  Treasury  Department. 

The  progress  of  work  on  shipbuilding  in  the  United  States  has  likewise 
been  retarded,  because  makers  of  steel  materials  required  a  higher  price  from 
the  American  consumers  than  they  did  from  the  foreign  consumers  for  sub- 
stantially similar  products.  Of  course,  American  exporters  have  to  get  for- 
eign contracts  in  competition  with  foreign  plate  makers,  who  are  excluded 
from  our  domestic  market.  In  addition  to  this,  American  export  plate 
makers  are  interested  in  preventing  the  establishment  of  plate  manufac- 
turing in  their  customer  nations  abroad,  and  to  that  end  bid  low  enough  to 
discourage  foreign  nations  from  entering  the  field  for  producing  their  own 
plate  at  home.  The  progress  of  domestic  maufacturers  of  iron  and  steel 
goods  may  likewise  be  handicapped  by  the  sale  of  iron  and  steel  in  their 
unmanufactured  state  at  so  much  lower  a  price  to  foreigners  than  to  domes- 
tic consumers  as  to  keep  the  American  competitor  out  of  foreign  markets 
generally.  The  natural  limit  to  such  a  policy  of  maintaining  a  higher  level 
of  prices  for  these  materials  at  home  than  abroad  is  found  in  the  restriction 
of  domestic  consumption  and  in  the  import  duty.  If  restriction  of  consump- 
tion at  home  does  not  operate  to  prevent  the  short-sighted  policy  of  dis- 
crimination against  domestic  development  of  manufacturing  industries,  the 
other  contingency  is  more  or  less  sure  to  arise,  namely,  the  demand  for  a 
reduction  of  the  tariff  on  unfinished  iron  and  steel,  in  order  to  equalize  the 
opportunity  of  makers  of  finished  products  in  foreign  markets.  To  this  policy 
the  domestic  consumer  is  usually  ready  to  lend  himself,  thus  making  a 
powerful  combination  of  interests  to  set  limits  to  the  rise  of  domestic  prices 
of  Iron  and  steel  materials.^ 

The  first  attempt  at  a  systematic  study  of  the  problem  was  made  by 
the  staff  of  the  Industrial  Commission  and  presented  in  its  report 
"Foreign  and  Domestic  Prices  of  American  Products."^ 

The  report  stated  that,  "In  view  of  the  frequent  assertion  that  ex- 
porters of  American-made  goods  often  sell  them  in  foreign  countries 
at  lower  prices  than  are  obtained  for  similar  goods  at  home,  the  Indus- 
trial Commission  has  endeavored  to  secure  from  the  business  interests 
of  the  United  States  a  full  and  frank  statement  covering  the  efforts 


^  Jacob  Viner,  TDumping :  A  Problem  in  International  Trade,  Chicago,  1923,  pp.  80-90. 
'  "Monthly  Summary  of  Commerce  and  Finance,"  August  1900,  p.  250,  Bureau  of  Sta- 
tistics, Treasury  Department. 

*:Report  of  the  Industrial  Commission,  1901,  vol.  XIII,  pp.  725-760. 

7 


Q  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

made  to  extend  consumption  of  products  in  foreign  markets."  The  in- 
formation was  obtained  directly  from  industrial  firms  by  question- 
naire on  a  voluntary  basi^  and  under  a  pledge  by  the  Commission  that 
answers  would  be  treated  as  confidential. 

The  Commission  sent  its  questionnaire  to  2,000  firms,  of  which  about 
715  replied;  416  answers  were  from  firms  engaged  in  exporting  and 
approximately  300  from  firms  which  stated  that  they  had  no  export 
business. 

The  method  used  to  obtain  information,  the  failure  of  the  Commis- 
sion adequately  to  define  price  and  to  specify  the  difference  in  the  type 
of  customer  in  domestic  and  export  markets,  leave  the  conclusions  that 
can  be  drawn  from  this  study  open  to  doubt.  It  was  concluded  that 
"The  great  majority  of  the  answers  indicated  that  prices  are  no  lower 
abroad  than  they  are  for  domestic  customers,  and  a  considerable  num- 
ber indicate  that  foreign  prices  are  higher."  As  to  just  what  is  meant 
by  "foreign  prices"  there  is  no  great  clarity.  For  example,  in  dis- 
cussing the  replies  received  from  textile  firms,  it  was  stated  that  "Of 
the  18  establishments  answering  the  schedules,  13  report  that  foreign 
prices,  or  the  prices  in  foreign  markets,  are  not  lower  than  those  in  do- 
mestic markets."  Because  of  the  confusion  that  must  have  existed  as 
to  exactly  what  prices  were  being  compared,  a  statement  of  this  char- 
acter has  little  meaning  except  that  it  does  show  that  there  were  five 
establishments  reporting  that  "foreign  prices,  or  the  prices  in  foreign 
markets"  were  lower  than  those  in  domestic  markets.  The  writer  can 
state  from  actual  experience  that  when  the  question,  "Do  you  sell  in 
foreign  markets  for  a  price  less  than  that  charged  for  exactly  similar 
articles  in  the  United  States?"  is  put  baldly  to  business  executives, 
the  answers  received  are  seldom  based  on  a  comparison  of  f .  o.  b.  factory 
prices  to  similar  classes  of  customers. 

Further  evidence  of  the  confusion  that  arose  from  the  wording  of 
the  questionnaire  is  apparent  from  the  answers  given  to  a  question  on 
the  reasons  for  differences  in  prices.  Of  the  reasons  of  a  permanent 
nature  "to  Avhich  are  ascribed  the  greatest  importance  are  those  of 
cash  payment  and  large  purchases  in  foreign  trade,  whereas  the  domes-, 
tic  trade  is  based  on  credits  and  small  purchases."  And  next  in  im- 
portance would  seem  to  be  "the  drawback  or  rebate  of  the  tariff  on  im- 
ported raw  material  of  goods  manufactured  for  export  and  "where  an 
allowance  is  made  from  the  internal  revenue  duties  in  case  of  exported 
goods."  Of  course,  as  ordinarily  conceived  these  cost  differences  are 
not  differences  in  prices  at  all. 

The  inadeauacy  of  the  study  led  to  different  opinions  of  the  im- 
portance of  the  practice,  both  as  to  its  extent  and  its  significance.  In 
Its  final  report  the  Commission  stated  that  "In  about  20  percent  of 
the  cases  covered  by  the  Commission's  returns,  the  export  prices  have 
ruled  lower  than  those  charged  to  home  customers."  The  Commission 
did  not  think  the  practice  was  confined  to  the  trusts  but  that  it  was 
quite  common  "on  the  part  of  the  separate  establishments  as  well  as  of 
combmations."  And  it  concluded  that  "It  is  probable  *  *  *  that 
when  the  export  prices  have  been  at  cost  the  result  has  been  by  keeping 
the  plants  fully  employed,  to  hold  the  prices  to  American  consumers 
lower  than  would  have  been  possible  otherwise.""     This  conclusion 

♦  Final  report  of  the  Industrial  Commission,  1902,  vol.  XIX.  pp.  626-627. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  9 

"was  based  on  testimony  of  interested  witnesses  rather  than  on  an  im- 
partial economic  analysis  of  the  problem. 

It  is  not  surprising  that  in  a  supplementary  statement  by  Thomas 
W.  Phillips  entirely  different  conclusions  were  reached : 

There  are  a  large  number  of  industries  iiL  which  it  is  in  evidence  that 
the  domestic  price  is  much  higher  than  the  export  price.  I  do  not  agree 
that  the  answers  to  inquiries  addressed  by  the  Commission  to  exporters 
indicate  that  the  trusts  are  not  chargeable  with  this  practice  to  any  serious 
extent.  Out  of  2,000  schedules  of  inquiries  sent  out,  there  were  received 
only  416  replies,  and  only  a  very  few  of  these  replies  came  from  corporations 
known  popularly  as  trusts  (vol.  XIII,  p.  726).  The  fact  that  about  75 
answers  indicated  lower  prices  abroad  than  at  home  is  significant,  when 
it  is  noted  that  more  than  four-fifths  of  those  addressed  failed  to  answer, 
and  that  naturally  those  who  are  chargeable  with  such  discriminations 
would  be  the  ones  who  would  decline  to  reply. 

Several  witnesses  before  the  Commission  on  behalf  of  the  trusts  admitted 
that  their  export  prices  were  lower  than  their  domestic  prices,  but  they 
contended  that  this  was  necessary  in  order  to  work  off  their  surplus  and 
to  keep  their  establishments  running  full  time,  and  that  all  manufacturers 
in  all  countries  do  the  same.  This  argument  overlooks  the  fact  that 
their  surplus  products  could  also  be  worked  off  by  lower  prices  at  home, 
and  that  it  is  the  tariff  which  encourages  them  to  cause  a  domestic 
surplus  by  restricting  domestic  consumption  through  high  prices." 

Among  the  Commission's  recommendations  is  included  the  following 
statement  relevant  to  this  problem : 

That,  in  view  of  the  extent  and  perfection  of  our  manufactures,  of  our 
growrig  export  trade  and  the  sharp  competition  it  encounters  in  foreign 
markets,  of  the  practice  by  some  exporters  of  making  lower  prices  abroad 
than  at  home,  and  of  the  desirability  of  protecting  the  consumer  as  well 
as  the  producer,  without  awaiting  other  legislation,  the  Congress  provide 
for  a  commission  to  investigate  and  study  the  subject,  and  to  report  as  soon 
as  possible  what  concessions  in  duties  may  be  made  without  endangering 
wages  or  employment  at  home,  what  advantages  abroad  may  be  obtained 
therefor,  and  also  to  suggest  measures  best  suited  to  gain  the  ends  desired.* 

A  more  extensive  report  on  comparative  domestic  and  export  prices 
was  prepared  for  the  New  York  Tariff  Reform  Club  and  reprinted 
in  the  Congressional  Record  of  June  7,  1906.'^  The  report  stated  that 
the  great  bulk  of  our  exports  of  manufactured  goods,  which  amounted 
to  ^52,000,000  for  the  year  ended  June  30,  1904,  were  sold  to  for- 
eigners at  prices  much  lower  than  those  prevailing  in  this  country.  It 
was  estimated  that  85  or  90  percent  of  our  exports  at  that  time  were 
sold  at  an  average  of  20  percent  less  than  domestic  prices. 

After  summarizing  the  available  evidence  in  official  sources  to  sup- 
port this  charge,  an  extensive  table  of  comparative  prices  was  pre- 
sented which  showed  export  prices  to  be  substantially  below  domestic 
prices  for  a  large  variety  of  manufactured  goods.  The  price  compari- 
son suffers  from  two  defects.  First,  the  report  does  not  name  the  firms 
to  which  the  prices  refer  or  give  any  other  evidence  of  their  authen- 
ticity. In  an  unofficial  report,  some  proof  of  the  accuracy  of  the  data 
would  be  desirable.  Second,  no  effort  was  made  to  adjust  prices  for 
any  difference  in  terms  and  conditions  of  sale  or  for  differences  in 
costs  that  might  have  existed.  The  domestic  prices  seem  to  be  whole- 
sale prices,  but  it  is  not  clear  to  what  class  of  customer  the  export 
prices  refer.  The  bulk  of  them  are  presumably  prices  to  export  com- 
mission houses,  which  handled  a  much  larger  volume  of  our  export 

»  Vol.  XIX,  p.  663. 

'  Congressional  Record,  vol.  40,  pt.  8,  59th  Cong.,  Ist  sess.,  pp.  8024-8033 


2Q  OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

business  in  those  days  than  at  the  present  time.  In  that  case  the 
manufacturer  would  have  had  no  selling  burden  on  his  export  busi- 
ness and  some  differential  between  the  domestic  and  export  prices  was 
to  be  expected.  The  report  is  therefore,  not  conclusive  as  to  the  size 
of  the  differential  beween  domestic  and  export  prices,  and  no  doubt 
overestimates  the  percentage  of  exports  sold  at  dumping  prices. 

The  Secretary  of  Commerce  and  Labor  was  directed  by  a  Senate  res- 
olution of  December  16,  1908,  to  supply  as  much  information  as  he 
could  regarding  American  manufactures  which  were  sold  for  lower 
prices  in  foreign  markets  than  at  home.  Two  reports  were  submitted 
to  the  Senate.^ 

The  difficulties  of  the  task  were  apparently  realized. 

To  secure  the  information  contemplated  by  the  resolution  of  the  Senate, 
and  arrange  it  in  form  that  would  present  the  facts  in  a  satisfactory  manner, 
would  require  the  services  of  a  person  who  has  had  experience  in  active  busi- 
ness and  who  has  practical  acquaintance  with  industrial  and  mercantile 
affairs,  including  knowledge  of  methods  employed  in  the  preparation  of 
goods  for  shipment,  charges  and  expenses  that  are  incidental  to  transporta- 
tion, entrance,  clearance,  discounts,  credits,  and  the  like.  Thorough 
equipment  of  this  character  is  deemed  essential  to  proper  and  impartial  in- 
vestigation. Ascertainment  of  prices  at  which  articles  are  sold  is  simple, 
requiring  no  special  knowledge ;  but  to  ascertain  causes  for  prevalent  prices 
or  conditions  that  may  be  abnormal  and  to  weigh  these  causes  impartially 
would  require  the  services  of  a  man  competent  for  such  work.' 

Prices  of  United  States  g(  jds  in  several  foreign  markets  were  sub- 
mitted in  the  reports  but  no  comparative  prices  for  the  domestic  mar- 
ket were  offered.  The  prices  were  reported  by  special  agents  with 
general  comments  to  the  effect  that  prices  in  the  foreign  markets  were 
not  lower  than  prices  for  similar  goods  in  the  American  market.  No- 
where in  the  reports  are  comparisons  made  of  the  manufacturers'  prices 
f .o.b.  mill  for  foreign  and  domestic  trade. 

On  May  27, 1926,  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  submitted  a  report 
on  "Alleged  Violation  of  Anti-Trust  Laws  by  Combinations  Being 
Formed  Abroad  by  American  Firms  and  Alleged  Dumping  of  Ameri- 
can Goods  in  Foreign  Markets."  "  The  study  was  made  in  response 
to  a  request  dated  March  24,  1925,  by  a  group  of  Senators  who  asked 
"whether  in  any  cases  American  goods  are  sold  cheaper  to  foreign  cus- 
tomers as  a  means  of  maintaining  the  prices  of  such  goods  manufac- 
tured in  the  United  States,  than  to  American  consumers." 

The  report  states  that  "a  general  survey  has  been  made  of  the 
principal  commodities  exported  from  the  United  States  *  *  *. 
Personal  inquiries  were  made  of  concerns  engaged  in  interstate  and 
foreign  commerce."  A  summary  of  the  replies  received  in  response  to 
the  inquiry  is  presented  which  consists  of  a  detailing  of  the  various 
types  of  policies  found.  There  is  no  indication  of  the  prevalence  of 
various  policies  and  little  mention  of  the  industries  which  use  the 
policies. 

In  a  concluding  statement  the  Commission  states : 

No  evidence  has  been  found  of  an  intention  to  export  at  lower  prices  as 
a  means  of  maintaining  high  prices  in  this  country.  On  the  contrary,  ex- 
porters contend  that  when  the  export  price  is  lower,  exportation  is  of  great 
advantage  to  the  industry  and  to  the  public,  because  it  serves  to  stabilize 


»n*P;«?,'^*^'   ^'<>-  6-  Manufactured  Products  Sold  In  Foreign  Markets  at  Lower  Rates  Than 
m  American,  pts.  1  and  2,  6lst  Cong.,  1st  sess 

•Ibid,  pt.  1,  p.  2. 

"  Mimeographed. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  IX 

production,  providing  an  outlet  for  surplus,  preventing  the  closing  down  of 
mills  and  mines  when  the  domestic  demand  is  temporarily  slackened,  and 
resulting  in  lower  production  costs  and,  consequently,  lower  prices  to  domes- 
tic purchasers.  *  ♦  *  From  the  standpoint  of  the  American  producer  or 
manufacturer,  two  arguments  against  dumping  are  suggested  by  concerns 
to  which  this  inquiry  was  presented.  It  is  insisted  that  goods  are  not 
dumped  (1)  because  it  would  be  an  Injury  to  the  company's  domestic  trade 
through  loss  of  gocd  will  of  the  American  consumer,  and  (2)  because  it 
would  be  an  injury  to  the  company's  foreign  trade  which  can  only  prosper 
in  the  long  run  by  establishing  permanent  foreign  markets  *  *  *.  It  Is 
also  claimed  that  "regular"  exporters,  those  selling  in  large  quantities  and 
expecting  to  stay  in  the  business,  are  selling  at  regular  intervals  and  gen- 
erally at  higher  prices  to  foreign  customers  than  to  domestic ;  that  the  prac- 
tice of  dumping  surplus  into  foreign  markets  at  irregular  intervals  and  at 
low  prices  is  used  less  and  less  frequently  and  will  continue  to  diminish  as 
our  foreign  trade  develops. 

The  best  study  and  the  only  recent  one  of  a  comparison  of  domestic 
and  export  prices  was  that  of  the  agricultural  implement  industry 
made  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission.  Considerable  care  was  exer- 
cised to  obtain  comparable  prices — that  is,  prices  which  refer  to  the 
same  commodity  under  similar  terms  and  conditions  of  sale. 

The  Commission  found  several  instances  of  sporadic  dumping. 
Goods  were  shipped  abroad  and  because  of  some  change  in  business 
conditions  could  not  be  sold  at  the  anticipated  price.  Prices  were, 
therefore,  cut  in  order  to  move  the  stocks  as  reshipment  to  the  United 
States  would  have  been  unprofitable.  The  bulk  of  the  exported  goods, 
however,  was  found  to  be  sold  at  the  same  prices  as  similar  goods  in 
domestic  sales. 

Other  bits  of  information  on  dumping  from  the  United  States  in 
earlie.'  years  are  available,  but  enough  has  been  given  to  indicate  its 
general  character.  A  good  portion  of  it  is  inconclusive  as  the  prices 
compared  are  not  really  on  a  comparable  basis.  It  is  furthermore  of 
little  value  for  the  present  study  because  the  bulk  of  the  information 
refers  to  conditions  of  20  years  or  more  ago.  The  only  study  of 
recent  years  is  that  of  the  Trade  Commission  on  agricultural  imple- 
ments. Thus,  it  was  necessary  in  the  present  study  to  obtain  from 
business  firms  the  primary  data  for  the  comparisons  of  domestic  and 
export  prices. 


CHAPTER  III 
SCOPE  OF  THE  FIELD  STUDY 

It  is  evident  from  this  brief  summary  of  previous  studies  of  the 
problem  that  available  knowledge  of  the  subject  would  be  inadequate 
for  the  Committee's  needs.  In  addition  to  inaccuracy  and  inconclu- 
siveness,  the  data  from  previous  studies  do  not  cover  current  business 
practices.  Nor  are  they  addressed  precisely  to  the  problem  in  a  way 
that  makes  them  adequate  for  present  purposes.  It  was,  therefore, 
necessary  to  make  a  field  survey  of  the  current  price  policies  of  busi- 
ness that  would  contrast  domestic  and  export  prices. 

For  two  reasons  it  was  considered  essential  that  the  information 
industry  could  furnish  be  obtained  by  personal  interview  with  the 
appropriate  business  executives  rather  than  by  relying  upon  a  mailed 
questionnaire.  The  probability  is  that  returns  to  a  questionnaire 
would  come  primarily  from  firms  which  did  not  have  lower  export 
prices  and  thus  bias  the  sample.  Furthermore,  the  character  of  the 
information  required  is  such  as  to  make  it  unlikely  that  accuracy 
could  be  obtained  except  by  interview.  This  is  due  to  the  difficulty 
of  framing  a  set  of  questions  which  would  leave  no  doubt  of  the  precise 
information  desired  with  resulting  indefiniteness  in  the  answers. 

The  data  were  obtained  through  conversations  with  the  executives 
of  each  business  concern  rather  than  by  sifting  the  evidence  out  of 
the  business  records.  The  reasons  for  this  are  that  an  executive  can 
answer  in  a  short  time  questions  which  the  records  could  reveal  only 
after  weeks  and  even  months  of  work  and,  furthermore,  certain  in- 
formation was  desired  which  would  not  appear  in  the  records.  As  the 
study  was  designed  to  be  qualitative  in  character,  rather  than  an. actual 
statistical  measurement  of  differences  in  prices,  the  desired  data  could 
more  quickly  be  obtained  by  this  method. 

In  order  that  business  executives  might  feel  free  to  speak  frankly 
about  the  policies  of  their  firms  and  be  under  no  apprehension  of 
unfavorable  reactions  upon  their  particular  business,  it  was  guaran- 
teed that  all  information  provided  the  investigator  would  be  confi- 
dential as  to  the  source,  and  that  nothing  would  be  published  to  reveal 
the  identity  of  any  firm.  It  was  relatively  easy  for  the  investigator 
to  arrange  the  order  of  his  questions  so  as  to  assure  himself  that  they 
were  being  answered  to  the  best  ability  of  the  business  executive.  It 
must  be  emphasized,  however,  that  the  analysis  of  the  cases  presented 
in  the  study  and  the  conclusions  reached  by  the  investigator  were  made 
independently  and  are  not  the  undigested  opinions  of  business  execu- 
tives. In  some  cases  the  persons  interviewed  might  not  agree  with  the 
conclusions  of  the  investigator. 

^"  this  basis  a  study  was  made  of  the  practices  of  what  might  best 
be  called  76  cases.  They  are  called  cases  rather  than  companies  or 
corporations  because  the  study  often  cuts  across  the  complications  of 
corporate  structure.  The  purpose  of  this  classification  was  to  in- 
12 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13 

elude  as  a  unit  for  discussion  the  relevant  domestic  and  export  price 
policies  for  a  particular  pi;oduct,  or  related  group  of  products,  regard- 
less of  whether  this  involved  more  than  one  corporation  or  only  part  of 
a  corporation.  For  example,  a  company  may  have  its  export  depart- 
ment incorporated  separately,  but  both  corporations  are  considered  as 
one  case  for  this  study.  An  export  house  may  handle  the  export  busi- 
ness of  as  many  as  40  independent  producing  companies  on  an  agency 
basis  or  otherwise,  but  the  combined  pricing  policies  are  counted  as  one 
case  in  this  report.  Several  of  the  cases  are  Webb-Pomerene  export 
corporations  formed  by  a  group  of  domestic  concerns.  Each  of  these 
corporations  and  its  group  of  producing  members  was  counted  as  one 
case.  On  the  other  hand,  one  corporation  may  have  two  or  three  pro- 
ducing departments,  each  making  a  different  line  of  products,  each  hav- 
ing its  own  export  division,  and  each  determining  its  selling  and  pric- 
mg  policies  in  accordance  with  the  conditions  of  the  industry  of  which 
it  is  a  part.  The  ideas  of  the  central  management  may  have  little 
effect  upon  the  price  policies  of  each  department.  In  such  circum- 
stances each  department  may  be  a  separate  case  for  the  purpose  of  this 
study. 

An  attempt  was  made  to  select  a  sample  which  would  illustrate  as 
many  type  situations  as  possible.  The  only  characteristic  which  all  the 
eases  have  in  common  is  that  in  each  an  active  effort  is  being  made  to 
secure  export  business.  The  volume  of  export  business  obtained  and 
the  proportion  it  bears  to  domestic  business  varies  considerably.  Many 
types  of  industries  are  represented  and  many  types  of  marketing  pro- 
cedures. Some  are  giant  corporations  and  some  are  moderate-sized 
businesses.  Some  are  known  td"  be  operating  under  a  noncompetitive 
price  system  in  the  domestic  market,  while  others  are  generally  con- 
sidered to  be  operating  in  highly  competitive  industries.  Some  are 
parts  of  world-wide  organizations  with  plants  in  many  parts  of  the 
world,  while  others  obtain  their  export  business  through  agents  in 
foreign  countries  without  the  aid  of  traveling  representatives.  The 
manufacturing  plants  are  widely  distributed  throughout  the  United 
States  with  the  executive  or  export  offices  located  in  New  York,  Phila- 
delphia, Pittsburgh,  Wheeling,  Chicago,  Buffalo,  Niagara  Falls,  and 
Rochester.  The  diversity  of  the  product  sample  may  be  appreciated 
from  the  following  list  of  the  principal  products  of  the  concerns 
studied : 

Foods 

Flour.  Branded  food  products. 

Packing-house  products.  Canned  fruits  and  vegetables. 

Evaporated  and  condensed  milk. 

Testiles  and  Theie  Products 

Cotton  yarn.  Girdles. 

Mercerized  cotton  yarn.  Women's  gloves. 

Silk  knitting  yarn.  Pajamas. 

Rayon  yarn.  Textile  finishers. 

Cotton  and  rayon  piece  goods.  Men's  collars. 

Cotton  staples.  Men's  shirts. 

Cotton,  turkish.  and  buck  towels.  Neckties. 

Silk  hosiery.  Felt  hats. 

Men's  cotton  hosiery.  Caps. 

Bed  sheets  and  pillowcases.  Straw  hats. 

Cotton  and  wool  blankets.  Handkerchiefs. 

Women's  underwear.  Sanitary  napkins. 


14 


(X)NCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Machinery  and  Transportation  Equipment 


Automobiles. 

Trucks. 

Adding  machines. 

Calculating  machines. 

Listing  machines. 

TjT)ewriters. 

Accounting  machines. 

Radios. 

Phonographs. 

Radio  tubes. 

Commercial  radio  equipment. 

Theatrical  recording  equipment. 

Theatrical  reproducing  equipment. 

Dyeing  machinery. 

Compressors. 

Pumps. 

Elevating  machinery. 


Conveying  machinery. 

Household  electrical  equipment. 

Household  electrical  appliances. 

Wood  building  machinery. 

Tractors. 

Sewage-disposal  machinery. 

Machine  tools. 

Air-conditioning  equipment. 

Heating  and  ventilating  fans. 

Sewing  machines. 

Diesel  engi-nes. 

Scales. 

Electrical  machinery. 

Electrical  refrigerators. 

Industrial  motors  and  generators- 

Electrical  supplies. 

Electrical  light  lamps. 


Chemical  and  Allied  Products 


Pharmaceutical  specialties. 

Chemicals  for  the  drug  trade. 

Pharmaceuticals. 

Biological  products. 

Home  necessities. 

Vitamin  products. 

Bulk  drugs. 

Automotive  chemicals. 

Insecticides. 

Industrial  lubricating  oils  and  greases. 

Textile  assistants. 

Chemical  specialtist  for  heat  treat- 
ment, processing  and  finishing  of 
metal  products. 

Paints. 

Glass,  Stone, 

Glass  bottles  and  jars. 
Glass  tableware. 
Tumblers. 
Safety  glass. 
Plate  glass. 


Lacquers. 

Enamels. 

Industrial  explosives^ 

Sporting  powders. 

Chemical  products 

Heavy  chemicals. 

Carbon  products. 

Ink  ribbons. 

Automotive  lubricants. 

Reagents. 

Abrasive  grains. 

Photographic  chemicals. 

Cosmetics. 

Writing  inks. 

AND  Clay  Products 

Plaster  wallboard. 
Acoustical  tiles. 
Structural  insulating  board. 
Lime. 
Plaster. 


Me^-al  Produots 


Pipe  fittings. 

Flush  valves. 

Plumbing  fixtures. 

Valves. 

Heating  equipment. 


Hand  saws. 

Band  and  circular  saww 

Tools. 

Metal  lath. 


Paper  and  Aixied  Products 


Paper  towels. 

Paper  and  stationery  specialties. 

Craft  board. 

Writing  paper. 

Printing  trades  paper. 


Cleaning  tissues. 
Toilet  tissues. 
Insulation  board. 
Reinforcing  building  paper. 


MlSCEIXANLDUS 


Men's  shoes. 
Phonograph  records. 
Cork  products. 
Leather  belting  and  packing. 
Cigarettes. 

Mining    and    industrial    safety    ap- 
pliances. 
Industrial  instruments. 


Commercial  measuring  instruments- 
Ophthalmic  instruments. 
Film  projectors. 
Cameras. 

Photographic  supplies. 
Abrasive  equipment  and  supplies.. 
Refractory  products. 
Laboratory  apparatus. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  15 

The  reader  will  note  that  while  this  list  covers  many  of  the  items 
Tvhich  are  important  in  our  exports  of  manufactured  products,  there 
are  many  omissions.  There  were  three  ^easons  why  the  list  is  not 
more  comprehensive.  The  omissions  which  appear  most  conspicuous 
are  due  to  the  fact  that  these  industries  are  being  studied  intensively 
at  the  present  time  by  other  executive  agencies  represented  on  the 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee.  Either  these  studies  will 
include  a  comparative  analysis  of  domestic  and  export  prices  or  else 
it  appeared  undesirable  to  impose  too  great  a  burden  on  a  small  group 
of  concerns  by  requesting  data  for  two  studies  at  once.  Any  other 
omissions  are  the  result  as  much  of  chance  as  of  any  other  factor. 
The  purpose  was  to  get  sufficient  coverage  to  reveal  the  basic  problems 
which  create  price  differences.  Diversity  of  industry  in  the  sample 
was  desirable  in  order  to  give  assurance  that  no  important  problems 
were  omitted.  But  when  it  was  felt  that  the  types  of  situations  exist- 
ing in  industry  were  rather  thoroughly  covered,  the  sample  was  con- 
sidered sufficiently  large.  It  is,  therefore,  to  a  large  extent,  accidental 
ihat  some  products  rather  than  some  others  are  in  the  list. 

It  must  be  stressed  that  the  emphasis  in  this  report  is  not  upon  the 
price  policies  relating  to  particular  products  but  upon  the  types  of 
policy  that  businessmen  use  and  find  effective.  A  sample  of  76  cases 
cannot  possibly  be  decisive  as  to  what  products  have  lower  export 
prices  or  higher  export  prices,  although  it  might  be  revealing  as  to 
w^hat  proportion  of  our  export  trade  is  sold  at  other  than  domestic 
prices.  Before  long  it  will  be  apparent  to  the  reader  that  in  many 
cases  a  product  sold  in  a  particular  way  by  one  manufacturer  may  be 
sold  under  an  entirely  different  policy  by  another  manufacturer.  All 
that  one  can  expect  to  do  with  the  limited  sample  under  review  is  to 
illustrate  the  various  types  of  situations  and,  insofar  as  is  possible, 
to  find  the  basic  conditions  determining  those  situations. 


CHAPTER  IV 

THE  PROBLEMS  INVOLVED  IN  COMPARING  DOMESTIC 
AND  EXPORT  PRICES 

Anyone  examining  the  invoices  of  most  manufacturing  establish- 
ments covering  the  sales  of  a  particular  product  for  even  as  short  a 
period  as  a  month  will  find  a  bewildering  array  of  prices  which  might 
appear  incapable  of  comparison.  The  complexity  of  the  compara- 
bility problem  will  be  evident  in  the  existence  of  different  prices  to 
retailers,  wholesalers,  distributors,  and  other  manufacturers,  f.  o,  b. 
prices  and  delivered  prices,  quantity  discounts,  advertising  allowances, 
varying  credit  terms,  combination  offers,  f.  a,  s.  prices,  c.  i.  f.  prices, 
agents'  commissions,  packing  enlarges,  or  the  nominal  prices  used  to 
record  transfers  of  the  products  to  subsidiary  companies  at  home  or 
abroad.  This  confusing  assortment  of  invoice  prices  attests  to  the 
fact  that  a  price  usually  includes  some  service  or  group  of  services  as 
well  as  the  product  itself  and  makes  it  clear  that  a  very  careful  defi- 
nition of  price  must  be  formulated  before  meaningful  comparisons 
between  domestic  and  export  prices  can  be  made. 

One  might  expect  tliat  precise  definition  would  be  found  in  the  vast 
body  of  antidumping  legislation  that  exists  throughout  the  world. 
But  the  standards  of  price  equality  which  are  elaborated  in  anti- 
dumping legislation  are  generally  inadequate  for  our  purpose.  They 
cover  a  variety  of  practices  or  types  of  dumping  which  have  no  rela- 
tion to  this  study  and,  furthermore,  the  definitions  are  in  such  general 
terms  as  to  have  little  meaning  unless  implemented  by  many  adminis- 
trative regulations.  The  general  character  of  antidumping  legislation 
can  be  seen  from  the  following  summary  from  a  report  of  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission  of  usual  provisions  for  which  dumping  duties  will 
be  imposed : 

(1)  Goods  imported  at  prices  less  than  the  "domestic  value,"  "market 
prices,"  or  the  "fair  market  value"  in  the  country  of  manufacture  or  export 
plus  expenses  incident  to  packing  and  transportation. 

(2)  Goods  imported  at  prices  less  than  the  cost  of  production  in  the 
country  of  origin,  or  less  than  the  cost  of  production  of  similar  goods  in  the 
country  of  importation. 

(3)  Importation  of  goods  sold  at  "less  than  a  reasonable  price,"  or  at  "an 
unfair  price." 

(4)  Importation  on  consignment,  of  goods  which  may  be  sold  at  less  than  a 
reasonable  price. 

(5)  Importation  of  goods  freight  free,  or  at  ballast  rates  of  freight,  or  in 
subsidized  ships  at  rates  of  freight  lower  than  the  freight  rates  prevailing 
at  the  date  of  shipment. 

(6)  Importation  from  a  country  in  which  the  exchange  value  or  currency 
has  depreciated,  resulting  in  prices  detrimental  to  industries  in  the  country 
of  importation. 

(7)  Importation  of  goods  upon  which  a  bounty,  bonus,  rebate,  or  subsidy 
has  or  will  be  granted  in  the  country  of  production  and/or  exportation.* 


•  Federal  Trade  Commission,  "Alleged  Dumping  of  American  Goods  In  Foreign  Markets," 
1926,  pp.  16-17.     (Mimeographed  report.) 

16 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  17 

JNIore  pertinent  definitions  can  be  derived  from  the  economic  mono- 
graphs on  dumping  which  have  classified  the  various  kinds  of  dumping 
and  discussed  in  specific  terms  dumping  by  the  producer.  Professor 
Viner,  for  example,  defines  dumping  as  "price  discrimination  between 
national  markets."^  In  explaining  the  meaning  of  this  definition  he 
makes  the  following  comments : 

In  the  definition  of  dumping  presented  above  the  term  "price  discrimina- 
tion" was  intentionally  used  in  preference  to  the  milder  phrase,  "sales  at 
different  prices."  In  the  growing  literature  on  unfair  competition  there  are 
traces  of  a  tendency  to  apply  the  term  "price  discrimination"  only  to  such 
instances  of  sales  at  different  prices  to  different  purchasers  as  are  not  readily 
to  be  explained  by  differences  in  the  conditions  and  terms  of  sale  governing 
the  different  transactions.  Given  this  interpretation,  "price  discrimination" 
may,  in  fact,  result  from  the  quotation  of  identical  prices  without  adjustment 
for  differences  in  the  terms  and  conditions  of  sale.  In  international  com- 
merce the  sale  at  different  pri.  to  purchasers  in  different  national  markets 
is  to  be  regarded  as  price  discrimination,  and  therefore  as  dumping  only  if  the 
different  prices  are  quoted  simultaneously  for  identical  or  substantially  iden- 
tical commodities  offered  for  sale  under  similar  conditions  and  terms,  or, 
where  these  last  are  not  similar,  only  if  the  price  differentials  embodies  what 
is  either  more  or  less  than  a  reasonable  allowance  for  the  differences  in 
conditions  and  terms.' 

Thus  it  is  obvious  that  quoted  prices  may  be  different,  and  yet  that 
tliis  difference  be  due  to  mere  differences  in  the  conditions  and  terms  of 
sale.  On  the  other  hand,  similar  prices  may  be  quoted  which  conceal 
an  actual  price  difference  because  the  conditions  and  terms  of  sale  are 
different. 

Hence  it  is  essential  in  comparing  domestic  and  export  prices  that 
the  terms  and  conditions  of  sale  in  both  cases  be  identical  or  else  that 
appro]:)riate  adjustments  in  quoted  prices  be  made  for  any  differences 
that  might  exist.  The  reason  for  tliis  is  that  differences  in  terms  and 
conditions  of  sale  often  arise  out  of  differences  in  costs  to  the  business 
organization,  and  it  is  an  establislied  principle  that  differences  in 
invoice  prices  are  not  discrimijiatory  when  they  reflect  differences  in 
costs.  Thus,  in  order  to  put  domestic  and  export  prices  on  a  com- 
parable basis,  adjustment  sliould  be  made  for  all  differences  in  costs  as 
between  the  two  spheres  of  operations.  Furthermore,  to  be  consistent 
the  adjustment  of  invoice  prices  for  differences  in  costs  should  be  made 
even  if  the  invoice  prices  are  identical.  For  example,  if  an  export 
shipment  required  an  extra  packing  cost  of  $10,  then  $10  should  be 
deducted  from  the  export  price  Avhen  comparing  it  with  the  domestic 
price.  If  the  invoice  prices  were  identical  before  the  adjustment,  then 
there  is  a  price  discrimination  of  $10  in  faA^or  of  the  export  customer. 
But  if  the  export  customer  had  been  billed  for  the  packing  cost,  domes- 
tic and  export  prices  would  be  equal  for  the  purposes  of  this  comparison. 

The  differences  in  the  conditions  and  terms  of  sale  Avhich  usually 
involve  differences  in  costs  and  which  should  be  allowed  for  in  price 
comparisons,  are  primarily  freight  costs,  duty  or  tax  refunds  on 
exports,  the  length  of  credit  terms,  extent  of  credit  risks,  the  s'ze  of 
orders,  packing  costs,  difference  in  the  selling  costs  required  to  get  the 
business,  and  difference  in  the  service  facilities  offered  in  diffi  rent 
markets.    Therefore,  in  order  to  assure  that  domestic  and  export  prices 

'  Viner.  op.  cit.,  p.  3. 
» Ibid.,  pp.  8-9. 


1§  CONCENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIG  POWER 

are  comparable,  the  following  conditions  should  be  fulfilled,  or  appro- 
priate adjustments  in  the  quoted  prices  should  be  made. 

(1)  The  price  comparison  should  be  made  for  products  which  are  identi- 
cal. If  there  is  any  special  manufacture  required  for  exports,  the  cost  must 
be  added  to  the  price. 

(2)  The  comparison  should  be  of  prices  quoted  on  the  same  date  or  dur- 
ing a  period  in  which  neither  the  domestic  nor  the  export  price  changed. 
Using  the  date  of  shipment  can  be  misleading,  for  there  may  have  been  a 
price  change  since  the  sale  was  made. 

(3)  Any  rebates  to  the  producer  from  duties  or  excise  taxes  paid  must  be 
deducted  from  the  export  price ;  or  if  exports  are  exempt  from  such  taxes, 
their  price  should  be  lower  by  the  amount  of  tax. 

(4)  The  comparison  should  be  made  on  an  f.  o.  b.  factory  basis  with  all 
freight  allowances  deducted. 

(5)  The  cost  of  extra  packing  required  for  export  should  be  allowed  for 
in  the  export  price. 

(6)  The  comparison  should  be  made  between  prices  quoted  to  similar 
types  of  customers  in  the  domestic  and  foreign  markets ;  i.  e.,  both  prices 
should  be  prices  to  wholesalers,  to  distributors,  to  retailers,  or  to  other 
manufacturers.  It  would  obviously  be  incorrect  to  compare  a  price  to 
retailers  in  the  domestic  market  with  the  price  to  wholesalers  in  the  export 
market. 

(7)  The  price  comparison  must  be  made  for  orders  of  similar  size. 

(8)  If  the  credit  risk  is  greater  in  either  market,  it  should  be  allowed  for 
in  the  price. 

(9)  If  engineering  or  other  services  are  supplied  without  charge  in  the 
domestic  market  and  not  abroad,  the  cost  of  such  services  should  be 
deducted  from  the  export  price. 

(10)  Differences  in  advertising  and  selling  costs  should  be  allowed  for  in 
the  price. 

(11)  Differences  in  quantity  discounts  or  credit  terms  offered  to  customers 
in  both  markets  should  be  considered  to  be  differences  in  prices. 

If  commodity  prices,  adjusted  for  all  of  the  foregoing  factors  which 
were  applicable,  could  be  obtained,  they  would  provide  an  accurate 
basis  for  comparing  domestic  and  export  prices  and  determining  in 
which  cases  export  prices  were  higher,  lower,  or  identical  with  domes- 
tic prices.  In  other  words,  it  is  the  factory  net,  or  mill  net,  on 
domestic  and  export  sales  that  should  be  compared.  Such  adjusted 
prices  represent  what  might  be  called  the  ideal  basis  of  comparability. 

This  conception  of  ideal  comparability  obviously  derives  from  the 
conditions  which  prevail  under  highly  competitive  conditions.  In  an 
industry  which  approximates  a  condition  of  pure  competition  one 
finds  that  virtually  every  productive  operation  and  every  distributive 
service  required  to  produce  the  commodity  and  get  it  into  the  hands 
of  the  consumer  is  performed  by  a  different  group  of  individuals  or 
business  concerns,  insofar  as  a  division  of  functions  is  technically 
feasible.  Each  functional  group  of  individuals  or  firms  adds  only 
one  link  to  the  productive  process  and,  therefore,  each  function  is 
individually  priced.  A  buyer  paj^s  only  for  that  combination  of 
functions  which  he  requires.  In  some  cases  where  one  individual 
performs  several  functions  there  are  competing  groups  who  are  will- 
ing to  render  each  of  the  several  services  so  that  the  buyer  has  a 
standard  of  comparison  that  enables  him  to  evaluate  the  worth  of  the 
combined  services  offered  him.  Each  service  in  the  entire  chain  has 
its  price  and  it  is  quite  simple  to  compare  the  prices  which  various 
buyers,  such  as  domestic  and  foreign,  pay  for  each  service  and  to  see 
if  they  are  equal. 

It  is,  of  course,  in  the  standardized,  or  accurately  graded,  commodi- 
ties wliich  are  produced  by  a  large  number  of  unorganized  producers 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  JQ 

and  sold  to  a  large  number  of  unorganized  buyers  that  one  finds  the 
nearest  approach  to  the  concept  of  pure  competition.  The  organization 
of  the  productive  and  distributive  process  of  wheat,  cotton,  apples,  and 
truck  crops  are  typical  examples  of  a  high  degree  of  competition  in 
the  contemporary  economic  system.  The  farmer  concentrates  his  at- 
tention almost  exclusively  on  one  function — growing  the  crop.  If  he 
also  delivers  the  product  to  the  railroad  station,  local  grain  elevator,  or 
nearby  city  market,  he  performs  this  service  for  his  entire  product — 
all  customers  get  the  benefit  of  it.  The  selling  function  is  undertaken 
by  independent  commission  men,  and  the  price  of  this  service  is  deter- 
mined independently  of  the  farm  price  of.  the  product.  The  major 
transportation  function  is  performed  by  another  group  of  individuals 
and  is  priced  independently  of  the  previous  services.  And  so  on 
through  the  entire  process  each  function — storage,  grading,  milling, 
financing,  and  so  forth — has  a  distinct  group  of  individuals  offering 
only  one  of  the  services  which  the  final  user  pays  for  when  he  buys  the 
product  delivered  to  his  place  of  business.  The  price  of  each  service  all 
along  the  line  is  independently  determined  and  is  well  known.  The 
user  has  the  privilege  of  entering  tlie  productive  process  at  any  stage 
and  of  paying  only  for  those  functions  that  have  actually  been  exe- 
cuted. The  price  of  wheat  is  lower  in  Chicago  than  it  is  in  New  York 
because  the  New  York  price  must  include  the  cost  of  transportation 
from  Chicago  to  New  York,  which  is  fixed  and  paid  for  independently 
of  the  price  of  the  wheat  without  transportation.  A  buyer  in  Buffalo 
will  not  pay  the  New  York  price  because  he  has  the  alternative  of 
buying  in  Chicago  and  shipping  to  Buffalo  at  a  total  cost  which  will  be 
less  than  the  New  York  price.  Similarly,  the  price  of  flour  is  higher 
]n  1-pound  ])ags  than  it  is  in  barrels  because  there  are  millers  who 
l-orform  only  the  one  function  while  others  perform  both,  and  the 
consumer  has  the  opportunity  of  buying  from  either.  Thus,  putting 
the  flour  into  1-pound  bags  is  an  independently  priced  function.  The 
differentiation  of  function  which  arises  from  a  multij^licity  of  pro- 
ducers and  a  multiplicity  of  buyers  acts  to  establish  an  independent 
price  for  each  service  in  the  productive  process,  and  thus  makes  possi- 
ble a  comparison  of  prices  between  markets  for  exactly  the  same  group 
of  services. 

Not  all  agricultural  products  exhibit  this  minute  separation  of 
functions,  because  tliere  is  a  high  degree  of  concentration  either  of 
selling  or  btiying  at  some  point  in  the  distributive  system.  And,  of 
course,  in  most  manufacturing  industries  the  productive  process  is 
highly  integrated,  even  in  what  is  usually  thought  of  as  nonintegrated 
industries,  so  that  the  buyer  at  any  stage  in  the  production-distribu- 
tion process  is  offered  a  variety  of  services  with  little  choice  of  s]:>ecify- 
ing  precisely  those  which  he  Avants,  Generally  speaking,  the  nearer  the 
product  gets  to  the  ultimate  constimer,  the  more  fuuctions  are  tied  up 
in  the  price  and  the  less  choice  the  buyei'  has  of  sorting  out  and  paying 
for  the  exact  functions  tiiat  will  meet  his  needs. 

For  example,  a  department  store  will  generally  offer  the  buyer  a 
commodity  at  a  price  Avhich  includes  a  charge-account  privilege,  gift 
))acka<>i7tg,  free  delivery,  and  exchange  services  if  those  are  desired,  but 
does  not  give  a  .pecial  price  to  the  customer  who  takes  none  of  these 
services.  Similarly,  many  manufactured  products  are  priced  to  include 
a  variety  of  services  and  often  no  allowance  is  made  if  the  buyer- does 

2."iT769— 11- 


20  OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

not  avail  liimself  of  the  services.  The  export  price  may  be  set  to  in- 
clude a  somewhat  different  group  of  services  and  it  may  be  impossible 
or  impracticable  for  even  the  manufacturer  to  compare  the  two  prices 
by  trying  to  make  the  two  groups  of  services  equal.  There  is  no  inde- 
pendent price  for  each  service,  and  it  is  often  impossible  and  mean- 
ingless to  assess  a  monetary  value  for  it. 

It  might  seem  that,  although  the  combined  services  included  in  the 
selling  price  are  not  priced  independently,  they  must  have  separate 
and  cleterminate  costs,  and  that  a  comparison  on  the  basis  of  costs 
would  be  feasible.  But  the  costing  problem  is  highly  complex.  In 
some  cases  it  is  impossible  to  allocate  costs,  except  by  arbitrary  meth- 
ods which  have  no  reality  but  in  the  accountant's  mind,  while  in  other 
cases  the  expense  of  doing  so  would  be  gi^eater  than  any  benefit  the 
businessman  could  derive  from  the  expenditure.  These  two  difficul- 
ties, joint  cost  allocation  and  the  expensiveness  of  costing  minor  items 
of  expense,  interpose  serious  obstacles  in  the  way  of  a  statistical  appli- 
cation of  the  conditions  pi-eviously  listed  as  requirements  of  price 
comparability.  A  brief  discussion  of  the  difficulties  encountered  in 
applying  some  of  these  conditions  will  illustrate  the  nature  of  the 
problem. 
Differences  in  the  Domestic  and  Export  Products. 

In  many  cases  a  manufacturer  must  adapt  his  product  to  meet  the 
needs  of  various  export  markets.  The  right-hand  drive  on  automo- 
biles, keyboard  adjustments  on  typewriters,  foreign-language  labels 
on  pharmaceutical  products,  and  different-colored  bands  on  hats  are 
interesting  examples.  Any  -of  these  changes  must  involve  some  addi- 
tion to  costs,  but  just  when  the  charge  is  substantial  enough  to  warrant 
an  addition  to  the  price  is  something  that  even  the  manufacturer 
cannot  always  answer.  The  automobile  companies  regularly  charge 
extra  for  right  drive ;  the  typewriter  companies  do  not  charge  for  key- 
board adjustments;  the  hat  manufacturer  does  not  charge  for 
style  adaptations;  one  pharmaceutical  house  computes  the  cost  of 
manufacture  of  foreign-language  containers,  while  another  pastes  a 
label  in  the  appropriate  language  over  the  English  printing  and  does 
not  cluirge  for  this  service.  In  some  cases  the  adaptation  of  the  prod- 
uct involves  a  cost  large  enough  to  be  allocated  and  added  to  the  price, 
but  in  other  eases  the  added  cost  is  too  small  to  botlier  with.  Even 
where  the  manufacturer  knoA\s  that  the  cost  is  substantial,  it  is  r.ot 
always  computed  separately,  for  in  some  instances  the  foreign  market 
price  will  not  allow  the  extra  cost  to  be  added  to  the  domestic  price. 

The  rule  adopted  in  this  study  has  been  to  accept  the  manufacturer's 
estimate  of  the  cost  of  special  manufacture.  If  he  considei-ed  the  cost 
substantial,  then  it  was  assumed  that  he  should  make  a  price  adjust- 
ment for  it,  and  that  if  he  did  not  adjust  the  export  price  he  was  then 
offering  a  lower  price  for  export.  Costs  that  were  too  r.egligible  for 
the  manufacturer  to  conceive  as  warranting  a  price  adjustment  were 
ignored  for  the  purpose  of  the  price  comparison. 

In  some  eases  the  firms  make  an  entirely  special  product  foi-  the 
export  market.  The  short-wave  radios  maiuifactured  for  the  Latin 
American  market  are  a  conspicuous  example.  It  was  found  that  the 
manufacturer  usually  knows  whether  the  profit  margin  included  in  the 
price  of  such  products  is  larger  or  smaller  than  the  customary  margin 
in  his  domestic  product.     Tlie  export  price  was  counted  as  higlier  if 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  2l 

the  profit  margin  (in  percentage  terms)  was  larger,  and  lower  if  the 
profit  margin  was  smaller. 

Some  situations,  however,  present  difficulties  which  defy  solution  in 
such  simple  terms.  The  problem  of  a  manufacturer  of  black  anrl  ^_^q1- 
vanized  pipe  fittings,  among  other  things,  is  an  interesting  one.  Pipe 
fittings  are  made  in  a  very  large  assortment  of  styles,  shapes,  and  sizes 
and  the  entire  assortment  is  made  in  two  thread  styles,  American  and 
British.  In  the  domestic  market  only  the  American  thread  is  used, 
while  both  American  and  British  threads  are  exported.  A  domestic 
and  export  price  comparison  for  the  American  thread  fittings  presents 
no  peculiar  difficulties.  But  how  is  one  to  compare  the  export  prices 
of  the  British  style  fittings  with  the  domestic  prices  of  the  American  ?' 
While  both  types  include  the  same  range  of  shapes  and  sizes,  the  pric& 
structures  are  entirely  different.  The  British  thread  price  structure 
originated  with  European  manufacturers  and  an  American  producer 
must  meet  those  prices  if  he  is  to  get  any  business.  The  two  price 
structures  differ  in  that  the  price  range  of  any  particular  product 
(as  an  L  or  union)  from  the  smallest  to  the  largest  size  is  much 
greater  for  the  British  than  for  the  American  thread.  The  smaller 
sizes  are  cheaper  and  the  larger  sizes  dearer  for  the  British  than  for 
the  American  thread.  The  smaller  sizes  are  produced  and  used  in- 
much  larger  quantities  than  the  larger  sizes — this  larger  production 
undoubtedly  being  the  reason  for  their  low  prices  in  the  British  thread 
price  structure.  But  the  American  producer  believes  that  if  he  sold 
only  small  sizes  at  the  Brititsh  thread  prices  he  would  lose  money, 
and  if  he  sold  only  large  sizes  the  profit  would  be  substantial.  Of 
course,  a  manufacturer  must  offer  the  whole  range  of  sizes  in  order  to 
meet  the  needs  of  his  customers.  It  would  obviously  be  very  difficult 
to  compare  the  two  price  structures  even  if  one  made  the  simplifying 
assumption  that  factory  costs  for  the  same  size  of  a  product  were 
identical  (which'  is  not  at  all  likely  because  they  are  produced  in 
different  quantities).  The  weighted  average  price  in  relation  to 
weighted  average  costs  would  have  to  be  the  basis  of  comparison,  but 
these  averages  would  change  from  day  to  day  or  month  to  month  as 
different  quantities  were  produced  and  sold.  And  with  the  tremen- 
dous variety  of  shapes  and  sizes  involved  the  expense  of  detailed  record 
keeping  would  be  prohibitive.  An  additional  difficulty  is  the  fact 
that  the  price  changes  in  the  two  sj^stems  do  not  occur  at  the  same 
time  and  are  not  always  in  the  same  direction  as  one  arises  from 
European  conditions  while  the  other  arises  from  American  conditions. 
All  things  considered,  one  must  agree  with  the  manufacturer  that 
the  British  and  American  thread  prices  are  not  comparable. 

Compai-h'^iov  of  Pr'toeft  Quoted  on  the  Same  Date. 

There  is  ordinarily  no  problem  in  obtaining  domestic  and  export 
prices  as  of  the  same  date.  In  some  cases,  hoAvever,  frequent  price 
changes  are  usual  in  the  domestic  market;  new  price  lists  are  sent  out 
once  a  month.  Such  frequency  may  not  be  possible  in  the  case  of 
exports  where  customers  are  spread  out  to  all  the  corners  of  the  earth 
so  that  new  export  price  lists  are  sent  out  only  once  a  year  or  when- 
ever major  price  changes  occur.  At  any  time,  therefore,  export 
prices  may  be  somewhat  above  or  below  domestic  prices,  or  some  above 
and  some  below.  These  cases  were  not  considered  as  differences 
between  domestic  and  export  prices  unless  the  one  was  consistently 
above  or  beloAY  the  other. 


22  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER. 

Rebates  on  Duties  and  Excise  Taxes  Paid. 

There  is  little  difficulty  in  applying  this  condition.  Of  course,  the 
drawbacks  are  sometimes  so  small  in  relation  to  the  value  of  the  prod- 
uct that  they  are  ignored  in  the  determination  of  the  export  price. 
The  excise  tax  on  cigarettes  and  automobiles  makes  a  sizable  difference 
in  the  price  of  those  products,  and  the  omission  of  the  tax  on  exports 
must  be  taken  into  account  in  comparing  prices.  But  a  manufacturer 
of  a  pharmaceutical  product,  which  wholesales  at  about  $8.50  per 
dozen,  mig^t  or  might  not  pass  on  to  his  export  customers  the  draw- 
backs on  sugar  and  alcohol  taxes  which  amount  to  only  21  cents  a 
dozen.  We  did  not  count  an  item  which  was  only  a  negligible  per- 
centage of  the  value  of  the  product  if  the  manufacturer  did  not  deduct 
it  from  the  export  price  as  a  difference  in  price  for  the  purpose  of  the 
price  comparison  presented  in  the  following  chapter. 

Price  ComparisoTis  on  an  F.  0.  B.  Factory  Basis. 

In  more  than  two-thirds  of  the  cases  that  were  examined  prices  were 
quoted  some  other  way  than  strictly  f.  o.  b.  factory.  A  few  manufac- 
turers who  sell  f.  o.  b.  factory  to  the  domestic  trade  quote  the  same 
prices  f.  a.  s.  New  York  to  export  customers.  Such  a  practice  clearly 
involves  a  price  concession  for  export  business  when  the  factory  is 
Tiot  located  on  the  seaboard.  Other  cases  in  which  export  prices  are 
quoted  f.  a.  s.  or  c.  i.  f.  according  to  the  custom  of  the  trade,  but  in 
which  the  exact  amount  of  the  inland  freight  is  added  to  the  f.  o.  b. 
factory  domestic  price,  are  clearly  cases  of  no  difference  in  prices. 
But  all  other  cases  present  more  or  less  difficulty. 

The  difficulty  arises  because  of  the  variety  of  freight  allowances 
that  may  be  included  in  the  price,  because  the  freight  costs  may  differ 
for  almost  every  customer  the  firm  has,  and  because  there  is  so  much 
difference  in  the  relation  of  freight  allowed  to  value  of  product.  In 
a  few  cases  freight  costs  are  so  high  that  the  manufacturer  must  keep 
accurate  account  of  his  costs  to  customers  in  various  locations  and 
adjust  prices  for  differences  in  freight  costs.  For  example,  a  producer 
in  New  Orleans  selling  at  one  price  delivered  in  the  United  States  has 
a  total  freight  bill  of  20  percent  of  receipts  from  domestic  sales.  In 
order  to  get  export  business,  his  f.  a.  s.  New  Orleans  export  price  is 
20  percent  less  than  the  domestic  price.  Since  we  are  here  concerned 
onlv  with  differences  between  domestic  and  export  prices  and  not 
with  discriminations  in  the  domestic  prices  themselves,  we  counted 
domestic  and  export  prices  as  identical  in  that  case. 

But  where  freight  costs  are  not  so  large  a  proportion  of  selling  price 
and  the  difference  between  export  and  domestic  freight  costs  not  so 
conspicuous,  a  neat  adjustment  of  prices  is  usually  impossible.  A 
few  examples  will  show  the  complications  involved.  Some  firms  lo- 
cated on  or  close  to  the  Atlantic  seaboard  have  zone  prices  for  the 
domestic  market;  the  price  for  each  zone  includes  freight  to  any 
point  within  the  zone.  The  zone  1  price  is  offered  to  export  customers 
f.  a.  s.  New  York.  Now  the  precise  costs  of  freight  to  all  customers 
in  zone  1  may  be  more  or  less  than  freight  costs  from  factory  to 
steamer  side  in  New  York,  and  it  may  vary  continually  according  to 
the  floAv  of  sales  in  the  domestic  market.  Furthermore,  the  differences 
between  the  domestic  zone  prices  may  not  be  exactly  equal  to  the 
difference  in  average  freight  costs  between  the  zones. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  23 

A  firm  located  in  New  York  State  sells  f.  o.  b.  its  regional  sales 
branches  to  its  domestic  customers  for  all  items  that  are  regularly 
carried  in  stock,  but  f.  o.  b,  factory  for  made-to-order  items.  In 
export  it  sells  all  orders  f .  a.  s.  New  York  City  for  freight  f .  o.  b. 
New  York  for  parcel  post,  but  it  gets  very  little  made-to-order  business 
from  export  customers.  In  any  event  the  freight  cost  from  factory  to 
New  York  City  is  very  small  in  relation  to  the  value  of  the  product. 
Now  the  average  freight  paid  by  the  company  on  export  businesses  less 
than  the  average  paid  on  other  business  in  New  York  City  (because 
the  domestic  customer  pays  the  freight  on  a  larger  proportion  of  the 
total  business)  but  it  is  less  than  the  average  for  all  United  States 
sales.  But  as  all  freight  is  a  relatively  minor  item  of  expense,  the 
company  does  not  keep  separate  accounts  for  freight  paid  by  domestic 
and  export  sales.  And  as  a  good  part  of  the  export  shipments  come 
out  of  stocks  of  the  New  York  City  sales  branch,  it  would  be  no  easy 
matter  to  allocate  freight  costs. 

Another  firm  located  near  the  eastern  seaboard  sells  at  one  de- 
livered price  throughout  the  United  States.  Total  freight  costs  on 
domestic  sales  is  a  rather  significant  item — about  12  percent  of 
domestic  sales.  The  company  believes  it  is  offering  export  cus- 
tomers the  same  conditions  by  quoting  identical  prices  for  export 
f.  o.  b.  any  port  in  the  United  States.  Consequently,  export  ship- 
ments move  out  of  New  York,  Philadelphia,  Baltimore,  Gulfport, 
Mobile,  Key  West,  New  Orleans,  San  Francisco,  and  Seattle,  accord- 
ing to  the  locations  of  the  export  customer,  available  shipping  facili- 
ties, and  ocean  freight  rates.  But  because  of  the  geographical  con- 
centration of  the  world's  population  and  buying  power,  a  larger 
proportion  of  the  company's  exports  leave  from  the  port  of  New 
York  than  the  proportion  of  domestic  sales  which  are  concentrated 
around  the  area  from  the  factory  to  New  York.  Consequently,  while 
the  company  is  offering  the  domestic  and  export  customers  the  same 
inland  freight  facilities,  its  average  freight  bill  per  unit  of  sales  is 
lower  for  export  business  than  for  domestic  business. 

Another  firm  located  in  the  vicinity  of  New  York  sells  to  all  cus- 
tomers, domestic  and  export,  at  the  same  price  f.  o.  b.  New  York,  but 
it  allows  freight  on  domestic  orders  of  over  $100.  The  purpose  of' 
this  practice  is  to  induce  the  customer  to  plan  his  buying  so  as  to 
avoid  the  expense  involved  in  many  small  shipments.  In  export 
there  is  no  inland  freight,  and  besides  the  customers  plan  their  buy- 
ing as  well  as  they  can  without  special  inducement,  because  the  dis- 
tances in  most  cases  prevent  rapid  delivery  and  they  must  be  pre- 
pared to  meet  their  needs  out  of  stock. 

These  examples  will  make  it  clear  that  some  more  flexible  formula, 
is  needed  than  an  attempt  to  adjust  prices  for  differences  in  the  cost 
of  freight  included  in  the  price.  For  once  goods  are  sold  on  other 
than  strictly  f.  o.  b.  factory  terms,  a  multiplicity  of  complications  arc 
introduced.  All  kinds  of  stipulations  are  made  to  suit  the  peculiari- 
tips  of  the  product,  the  domestic  market,  and  the  export  market. 

For  the  purpose  of  our  price  com])arison,  the  following  procedure 
was  adopted.  F.  o.  b.  prices  were  used  wherever  they  are  the  basis 
of  varying  price  quotations.  Where  exports  are  sold  c.  i.  f.  the  ocean 
freight  and  insurance  costs  were  deducted  from  the  export  price  to 
provide  a  basis  of  comparison  with  domestic  prices.     In  all  cases 


24,  OONCENTIIATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

where  the  producer  offered  the  same  conditions  with  regard  to  in- 
land freight  to  export  customers  as  to  domestic,  no  price  adjustment 
was  made  even  though  actual  freight  costs  were  not,  as  tliey  could 
hardly  ever  be,  identical.  Furthermore,  no  price  adjustment  was 
made  where  the  freight  conditions  were  dissimilar  if  the  purpose  of 
the  difference  was  to  expedite  business  procedure.  But  a  price  ad- 
justment was  considered  necessary  where  the  special  conditions 
offered  to  export  or  domestic  customers  was  in  lieu  of  a  price  con- 
cession. 

Adjustment  for  Cost  of  Special  Packing. 

Ordinarily  it  is  not  difficult  to  make  a  price  adjustment  for  the 
cost  of  packing.  Where  this  cost  is  a  sizable  item,  the  manufacturer 
is  well  aware  of  the  cost  and  knows  whether  the  export  price  is 
sufficiently  higher  to  cover  the  cost.  In  some  cases  the  cost  is  so  smalJ 
in  relation  to  tlie  vaUie  of  the  product  that  the  manufacturer  prefers 
to  ignore  it,  and  we  have  accepted  his  judgment.  For  example,  in 
shipping  adding  machines  packed  three  in  a  case,  one  firm  slips  the 
regular  package  into  another  case  for  export  shipment.  The  value 
of  the  three  machines  is  well  over  $100  and  the  extra  case  costs  less 
than  25  cents.  It  hardly  seems  reasonable  to  consider  this  a  price 
discrimination.  In  fact,  the  manufacturer  said  that  he  did  not  add 
the  cost  to  the  export  jjrice  because  it  never  occurred  to  him  to  charg>? 
for  the  extra  container. 

Some  cases  present  complexities.  A  lightweight  product  is  sold 
in  the  domestic  market  and  in  many  export  markets  in  a  paper-board 
container  that  weighs  ahnost  as  much  as  tlie  })roduct  itself.  The  man- 
ufacturer's price  covers  the  product  and  container.  In  some  ex])ort 
markets  duty  is  assessed  by  gross  weight,  and  the  product  of  this  com- 
pany plus  container  would  have  to  pay  almost  twice  as  much  duty  as 
the  products  of  competing  manufacturers  which  are  sold  without  con- 
tainers. Hence,  the  price  in  those  export  markets  would  be  too  high 
to  attract  consumers.  The  company,  therefore,  ships  to  dealers  in  those 
countries  without  containers  and  gives  them  an  allowance  which  ap- 
proximately covers  the  cost  of  })ackaging  in  the  dealer's  country.  As 
the  dealer  in  each  country  only  ])ackages  a  small  volume  in  comparison 
to  the  output  of  the  firm  itself  in  the  United  States,  his  cost  per  pack- 
age is  larger  than  the  cost  in  the  United  States  so  that  the  net  to  the 
company  is  lower  on  sales  of  this  product  to  those  countries.  We  did 
not,  however,  count  this  as  a  reduction  in  the  export  price.  Anothei" 
firm  sells  its  product  unpackaged  for  export  and  gives  a  large  allow- 
ance for  the  purpose  of  meeting  foreign  competition.  The  allowance 
is  much  larger  than  the  cost  of  packaging,  here  or  abroad.  In  this  case 
we  did  count  the  export  price  as  lower  than  the  domestic  price. 

Comparing  Prices  Quoted  to  Similar  Types  of  Buyers. 

This  provision  is  very  difficult  to  apply  in  some  cases  and  impossible 
to  apply  in  a  few  instances.  When  the  firm  has  some  customers  of  the 
same  type  in  the  domestic  and  export  market,  the  prices  to  identical 
types  of  customers  can  be  compared.  But  when  there  is  no  equivalent 
of  the  domestic  type  of  customer  in  export  markets  and  vice  versa,  the 
comparison  of  prices  is  not  a  simple  matter. 

In  the  first  place  the  division  of  the  distributive  function  among  re- 
tailers, wholesalers,  and  distributors  that  is  a  characteristic  of  the 


CXDNCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  25 

United  States,  simply  does  not  exist  in  many  parts  of  the  world  as,  for 
example,  in  many  Latin  American  countries.  The  distribittive  func- 
tion may  be  divided  between  importers  and  merchants,  but  the  im- 
porter may  sell  direct  to  the  consumer  as  well  as  to  nonimporting  mer- 
chants, or  he  may  sell  only  to  the  consumer.  The  American  producer, 
Avho  does  not  have  extensive  field  representation,  may  not  even  know 
what  functions  these  foreign  customers  perform,  and  he  is  apt  to  clas- 
sify them  as  wliolesalers  without  much  investigation.  We  did  not  chal- 
lenge the  classification  of  customer  which  the  firm  found  it  necessary 
to  make. 

But  real  difficulties  arise  in  the  following  types  of  cases.  A  domestic 
maiuifacturer  maintains  his  own  retail  branches  in  the  United  States. 
All  his  domestic  sales  are  direct  to  consumer,  but  export  sales  are  to 
wholesalers  and  retailers.  The  expense  of  maintaining  the  retail 
branches  varies  from  about  33  to  47  percent  of  the  branches'  sales  and, 
of  course,  the  total  varies  from  year  to  year  according  to  the  total 
volume  of  business  and  the  sales  of  each  branch.  If  the  discount 
offered  to  export  customers  was  an  approximation  of  the  average  cost 
u»  tlie  company  of  the  selling  function  we  counted  the  prices  as  identi- 
cal, but  if  it  was  consistently  larger  Ave  counted  the  export  price  as 
lower  than  the  domestic. 

Another  firm  sells  in  all  the  heavily  populated  areas  of  the  United 
States  through  retail  branches  but  appoints  exclusive  dealers  for  a 
few  thinly  populated  areas.  The  discount  which  the  firm  nnist  give 
these  dealers  to  induce  them  to  stock  and  sell  the  product  is,  of  course, 
based  upon  a  realization  of  the  costs  of  doing  business  in  thinly  popu- 
lated areas  and  is  larger  than  the  actual  costs  of  the  company's  retail 
branches  located  in  heavily  populated  areas.  The  company  also  sells 
abroad  through  exclusive  dealers  and  grants  them  the  same  discount 
as  is  given  the  exclusive  dealers  in  the  domestic  market.  Now  ob- 
viously the  net  return  on  exports  is  lower  than  on  domestic  business 
since  the  costs  of  the  company's  retail  branches  are  less  than  the 
dealers'  discount.  We  did  not,  however,  consider  that  this  procedure 
involved  a  price  concession  to  the  export  customer. 

Equal  Credit  Terms  to  Domestic  and  Export  CustOTners. 

In  a  large  majority  of  the  cases  covered  in  the  field  survey,  it  was 
found  that  longer  terms  are  extended  to  export  customers  than  to 
domestic  customers.  In  general,  the  longer  extension  of  credit  is 
designed  to  cover  the  longer  time  required  for  shipment  of  goods 
and  transmission  of  documents.  The  time  that  the  export  customer 
has  possession  of  the  goods  without  payment  is  generally  no  longer 
than  the  time  a  domestic  customer  would  have  them.  In  almost  all 
cases  the  cost  involved  in  this  longer  extension  of  credit  is  absorbed 
by  the  shipper.  If  the  absorption  of  this  cost  were  to  be  considered  a 
price  concession  on  exports,  then  almost  all  cases  which  would  other- 
wise have  identical  domestic  and  export  prices  would  have  higher 
domestic  than  export  prices.  As  this  would  not  be  a  useful  distinction 
for  the  purposes  of  this  study,  such  differences  in  credit  terms  were 
ignored  in  making  the  price  comparisons.  In  a  few  cases,  however, 
very  long  credit  terms  of  6  to  9  months  are  extended  to  export  cus- 
tomers where  domestic  customers  are  limited  to  30  days,  and  the  pur- 
pose is  to  give  an  added  inducement  to  the  export  customer.  As  this 
extension  of  credit  is  in  lieu  of  a  price  concession,  we  did  consider  that 


26  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

an  adjustment  of  the  export  price  in  these  cases  was  necessary.  It 
so  happened  that  in  the  cases  covered  all  those  which  extended  un- 
usually long  credit  terms  also  made  actual  price  concessions  in  export 
and,  therefore,  would  have  been  classified  as  having  lower  export  than 
domestic  prices  regardless  of  credit  terms. 

These  illustrations  are  sufficient  to  indicate  that  there  are  many 
difficulties  in  the  way  of  a  strict  adjustment  of  prices  for  all  differ- 
ences in  cost,  although  they  do  not  preclude  the  drawing  of  reasonable 
conclusions.  Even  if  one  considered  that  that  principle  should  be 
rigidly  applied,  it  would  be  necessary  to  adopt  certain  simplifying 
statistical  procedures  as  indi<;ated  above.  But  as  a  comparison  of 
prices  must  be  made  in  accordance  with  actual  business  practices, 
situations  occur  which  leave  some  doubt  as  to  the  applicability  of  the 
principle  itself.  It  is  not  that  costs  in  these  cases  are  indeterminate, 
but  that  the  relevancy  of  adjusting  prices  for  differences  in  cost  is 
itself  doubtful. 

In  many  cases,  the  distinction  between  domestic  and  export  sales 
is  an  artificial  one  from  a  business  standpoint.  One  might  find  that 
the  relative  costs  of  many  items  of  expense  were  different  for  export 
than  for  domestic  business,  due  entirely  to  accidental  factors.  In 
fact,  the  same  type  of  cost  differences  would  be  found  between  different 
areas  of  a  company's  operations  within  the  United  States.  For 
example,  a  sales  branch  in  one  of  the  densely  populated  eastern  States 
might  have  relatively  lowf  *  costs  than  that  in  a  western  territory. 
Similarly,  it  might  be  rela  ively  more  or  less  expensive  tlian  a  Latir 
American  branch.  And  yec,  if  all  the  branches  of  the  company  were 
charged  at  the  same  price  by  the  factory,  it  would  seem  only  common 
sense  to  consider  domestic  and  export  prices  equal. 

It  is  generally  with  regard  to  selling  costs  that  it  seems  mapplicable 
to  adjust  prices  for  all  cost  differences  as  between  domestic  and  ex- 
port operations.  A  typical  example  is  that  of  a  firm  which  advertises 
in  the  domestic  market  where  the  bulk  of  its  sales  are  concentrated 
but  does  not  advertise  in  its  far-flung  export  markets,  each  of  which 
absorbs  only  a  small  share  of  its  total  sales.  This  company  sells  its 
product  for  the  same  price  f.  o.  b.  factory  to  all  customers,  foreign 
or  domestic.  If  one  were  to  adjust  the  domestic  price  for  the  dif- 
ference in  advertising  cost,  the  net  result  would  be  that  the  export 
Erice  would  be  higher  than  the  domestic  price,  which  would  seem  to 
e  an  unreasonable  conclusion.  The  procedure  followed  in  this  study 
was  to  ignore  differences  in  cost  of  this  type.  Another  firm,  however, 
does  its  own  advertising  in  the  domestic  market  but  grants  an  adver- 
tising discount  to  its  exclusive  distributors  in  foreign  markets.  The 
invoice  price  to  its  export  customers  is,  therefore,  lower  than  the 
domestic  price  by  approximately  its  advertising  cost  in  the  domestic 
market.  In  cases  of  this  type  we  also  considered  domestic  and  export 
prices  to  be  equal. 

Situations  such  as  these  indicate  that  prices  should  not  be  adjusted 
for  all  differences  in  costs.  With  strict  adherence  to  the  principle  of 
cost  equality  it  is  improbable  that  any  cases  of  equal  domestic  and 
export  prices  could  be  found.  Thus,  in  order  to  yield  more  reason- 
able conclusions  the  comparison  of  prices  in  this  study  was  made  on 
the  basis  of  an  approximation  of  the  factory  net  back  on  domestic 
and  export  sales — approximations  such  as  are  used  by  business  itself. 
The  problems  mentioned  above  are  of  a  conceptual  character,  but 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  27 

there  are  others  more  statistical  in  nature.  These  examples  were  con- 
cerned with  the  question  of  when  an  adjustment  of  invoice  prices  was 
necessary  to  insure  comparability.  For  each  of  them  had  only  one 
factor  which  had  to  be  taken  into  account ;  that  is,  the  terms  and  con- 
ditions  of  sale  were  substantially  identical  except  for  one  sij^nificant 
difference  for  which  an  adjustment  could  be  made  on  the  basis  of  the 
difference  in  costs.  But  most  cases  present  many  differences  in  the 
terms  and  conditions  of  sale  and  many  differences  in  the  cost  to  the 
company  of  supplying  identical  services  for  domestic  and  export 
business  with  the  cost  differences  being  larger  for  export  on  some  items 
and  larger  for  domestic  on  other  items.  For  example,  a  firm  sells  in 
the  domestic  market  f.  o.  b.  factory  at  2/10  net  30,  at  three  different 
prices  to  consumers,  retailers,  and  wholesalers,  gives  quantity  dis- 
counts on  some  items,  has  salesmen  working  on  salary  and  commission, 
maintains  branch  sales  offices  in  some  localities,  does  considerable  ad- 
vertising, and  gives  its  customers  technical  advice  and  engineering 
service  when  necessary.  For  export  it  sells  at  domestic  prices  f.  a.  s. 
New  York,  boxes  for  export  without  charge,  gives  credit  terms  up  to 
90-day-date  draft,  has  a  few  traveling  representatives  to  stimulate  tha 
foreign  dealer  by  showing  him  how  to  market  the  product,  has  a  few 
special  discounts  to  exclusive  representatives  in  certain  export  markets, 
does  no  advertising  abroad,  has  certain  special  expenses  such  as  cables, 
freight  forwarder's  fees,  consular  fees,  pays  commissions  to  foreign 
agents,  but  offers  no  technical  or  engineering  services  in  export  mar- 
kets and  no  quantity  discounts.  It  can  be  seen  that  the  task  of  adjust- 
ing domestic  and  export  prices  for  all  these  differences  would  be 
enormous,  especially  when  the  cost  of  any  one  item  is  not  substantial 
enough  for  the  manufacturer  to  consider  a  price  difference  warranted 
on  the  basis  of  it.  The  problem  is  further  complicated  when,  as  in 
many  cases,  the  manufacturer  does  not  sell  at  uniform  prices  for  export 
but  has  different  prices  in  different  markets  depending  upon  costs 
or  local  competitive  conditions. 

As  a  practical  matter,  therefore,  the  procedure  of  comparing  prices 
must  be  simplified  to  statistically  manageable  rules.  The  following 
method  was  used  in  this  study : 

Where  invoice  prices  were  the  same  for  the  same  types  of  customers, 
domestic  and  foreign,  and  there  was  no  individual  difference  in  terms 
and  conditions  of  sale  or  costs  of  doing  business  substantial  enough  by 
itself  to  make  the  net  return  different,  we  counted  prices  as  identical. 
Where  invoice  prices  were  different  and  the  differences  were  due  to 
specific  adjustments  for  differences  in  the  cost  of  doing  business,  we 
counted  the  prices  as  identical.  Where  invoice  prices  were  different 
but  the  difference  was  due  to  market  conditions,  the  export  price  was 
counted  as  lower  or  higher  as  the  case  may  be.  Where  prices  were  the 
same  but  there  was  a  substantial  difference  in  the  costs  of  doing  business 
or  the  services  included  in  the  price,  export  prices  were  counted  as 
higher  or  lower  as  the  facts  indicated. 

An  actual  computation  of  the  degree  of  difference  in  prices  for  even  a 
small  sample  would  have  involved  a  heavy  cost  and  considerable  time, 
which  seemed  inappropriate  to  the  purpose  of  the  report.  All  that 
was  done,  therefore,  was  to  determine  if  export  prices  were  higher  or 
lower  than  domestic  prices. 

Another  complication  arises  in  the  fact  that  many  firms  sell  a  variety 
of  products  to  many  foreign  markets,  and  their  price  policy  is  not  the 


28  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

same  for  all  products  and  all  markets.  Some  products  are  sold  at 
higher  than  domestic  prices,  some  are  sold  at  the  same  as  domestic 
prices,  and  some  lowei'.  There  is  a  similar  variation  from  market  to 
market.  In  other  words,  it  is  often  impossible  to  give  a  simple  de- 
scription to  a  firm's  price  policy  by  saying  that  it  exports  at  lower  or 
higher  prices  or  at  prices  identical  with  domestic  quotations.  For  it 
may  be  doing  all  three  things  at  the  same  time.  A  comparison  of 
average  prices  in  export  and  domestic  trade  would  often,  therefore, 
conceal  the  details  which  are  of  primary  interest  in  this  study.  For 
this  reason  an  attempt  at  two  comparisons  between  domestic  and  ex- 
port business  was  made — one  concerns  prices,  the  other  profits. 

The  cases  examined  in  the  field  survey  have  been  divided  into  three 
groups,  on  the  basis  of  price  policy.  The  prices  compared  in  all  cases 
were  adjusted  prices — not  invoice  prices.  Group  I  includes  those  for 
Avhich  all  or  some  export  prices  are  higher  than  domestic  prices,  but  no 
export  prices  are  lower  than  domestic  prices.  Some  export  prices  may 
be  equal  to  domestic  prices,  either  for  certain  products  or  to  certain 
countries,  but  none  are  lower.  Group  II  includes  all  cases  for  which 
export  prices  are  equal  to  domestic  prices ;  none  are  higher  and  none 
lower.  Group  III  includes  those  cases  for  which  some  export  prices, 
adjusted  as  indicated  above,  are  lower  than  domestic  prices.  In  these 
cases  export  prices  may  be  in  part  equal  or  higher  than  domestic  but 
some  prices  are  lower.  The  details  of  price  policy  are  given  accord- 
ing to  the  various  types  classified  under  each  group. 

The  comparison  of  the  profitability  on  export  and  domestic  sales  was 
made  in  order  to  indicate  the  overall  or  average  relation  of  export  and 
domestic  prices.  It  is  clear  that  if  adjusted  export  prices  on  a  par- 
ticular product  to  a  particular  country  are  lower  than  domestic  prices 
then  the  profit  margin  on  those  export  sales  is  lower  than  on  domestic 
sales.  The  process  of  adjusting  prices  is  a  process  of  allowing  for 
significant  differences  in  costs.  Hence,  a  net  difference  in  price  is  a 
difference  in  the  margin  of  profit  on  that  portion  of  exports.* 

The  comparison  of  profit  margins  on  United  States  sales  with  all 
export  sales  measures  the  difference  between  the  avei-age  of  all  domes- 
tic prices  (adjusted)  and  all  export  prices  (adjusted).  It  indicates, 
however,  two  things  which  are  neglected  by  the  price  comparison. 
First,  it  may  show  that  there  are  some  small  differences  in  costs  which 
could  not  be  considered  large  enough  to  wan-ant  a  price  adjustment. 
For  this  reason  a  case  in  grou])  II  of  export  and  domestic  prices  equal 
may  have  a  higher  or  lower  margin  of  profit  on  exj)ort  sales.  All  the 
cases  in  group  I,  how^ever,  have  a  higher  margin  of  profit  on  exports. 
Second,  it  can  show  that  lower  export  prices  for  a  portion  of  a  firm's 
exports  may  be  offset  by  higher  prices  for  other  portions.  Thus,  som& 
of  the  cases  in  group  III  which  have  some  lower  export  prices  also 
have  higher  profits  on  export  sales. 

In  the  comparison  of  profits,  all  direct  costs  of  doing  domestic  or 
export  business  were  to  be  cliarged  against  those  sales  to  which  they 
applied  and  overhead  or  joint  costs  strictly  allocated  on  tlie  basis  of 
sales.  Each  sales  department,  domestic  and  exjiort,  was  to  be  charged 
with  its  full  costs  including  overhead. 


*  The  margin  of  profit  refers  to  nverase  profit,  of  course,  not  mar>;itinl  profit. 


CHAPTER  V 

COMPARISON  OF  EXPORT  AND  DOMESTIC  PRICE 

POLICIES 

In  this  chapter  will  be  presented  a  summary  of  the  price  policies 
and  comparative  profitability  of  domestic  and  export  sales  for  the  76 
business  enterprises  covered  by  the  field  study.  This  summarization 
is  necessarily  an  oversimplification  of  the  facts  since  there  are  peculi- 
arities in  the  selling  practices  of  every  business  organization  which  in 
one  way  or  another  make  it  an  individual  case.  The  cases  are  classi- 
fied into  three  main  groups  and  subclassified  into  various  types, 
according  to  the  predominant  characteristic  of  the  export  price  pol- 
icy. In  this  way,  the  pledge  not  to  disclose  the  identity  of  any  busi- 
ness organization  which  supplied  this  information  is  not  violated  as  it 
would  be  if  complete  descriptions  of  products  and  practices  were 
given  case  by  case.  Such  a  classification  of  the  cases  based  upon  the 
dominant  characteristic  of  the  price  policy,  which,  so  to  speak,  stressed 
the  rationale  of  the  price  policy,  reduces  the  data  to  manageable  form 
and  more  clearly  reveals  the  essential  facts. 

The  primary  classification  of  the  76  cases  has  been  made  on  the 
basis  of  the  comparison  of  domestic  and  export  prices  as  defined  in 
chapter  IV.  Thus,  the  cases  fall  into  three  groups — those  with  ex- 
port prices  higher  than  domestic  prices,  export  prices  equal  to  domes- 
tic prices,  and  export  prices  lower  than  domestic  prices.  The  cases 
are  further  subdivided  into  13  types,  according  to  the  dominant  fea- 
ture of  the  price  policy.  This  essential  feature  of  the  export  price 
policy  may  be  either  the  guiding  principle  behind  the  price  policy,  or 
an  expression  of  the  conditions  or  results  achieved  by  the  price  pol- 
icy or  both.  One  or  more  examples  of  each  type  will  be  given  in 
order  to  show  the  details  of  price  policy. 

If  export  prices  are  higher  than  domestic  prices  after  the  adjust- 
ment, then  export  sales  are  presumably  more  profitable  than  domestic 
sales  and  vice  versa.  However,  the  following  distinction  must  be 
made  between  the  comparison  of  prices  and  the  comparative  profit- 
ability of  domestic  and  export  sales  as  a  whole.  Where  a  business 
organization  makes  some  of  its  export  sales  at  net  prices  identical  to 
domestic  prices  and  some  of  its  export  sales  at  net  prices  higher  than 
domestic  it  has  been  put  into  group  I — export  prices  higher  than  do- 
mestic prices.  Where  the  business  organization  consummates  any  sig- 
nificant portion  of  its  export  business  at  net  prices  lower  than  domes- 
tic prices  so  that  its  net  profit  on  that  portion  of  its  sales  is  lower 
Ihan  the  net  profit  on  its  domestic  sales  it  has  been  classified  into 
group  III — export  prices  lower  than  domestic  prices.    In  some  of  these 

29 


30  OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

cases  the  profitability  of  export  business  as  a  whole  may  be  just  as 
great  as  the  profitability  of  domestic  business  and  in  some  cases  the 
export  business  as  a  whole  may  be  more  profitable.  Moreover,  as  the 
price  comparison  is  based  upon  an  approximation  of  the  factory  net 
on  domestic  and  export  sales  while  the  profit  comparison  is  based 
upon  a  precise  computation  of  factory  net  including  all  selling  and 
incidental  costs,  the  results  of  these  two  comparisons  are  sometimes 
different.  The  number  of  cases  which  have  these  various  profit  expe- 
riences will  be  indicated  in  the  discussion  to  follow. 

The  reader  will  remember  that  in  the  comparison  of  the  net  profit 
on  domestic  and  export  business  all  costs  must  be  allocated  with  no 
special  preference  given  to  either  the  domestic  or  export  sales.  That 
is,  per  unit  factory  costs  for  identical  products  must  be  the  same  and 
where  the  products  are  not  identical  the  exact  factory  costs  must  be 
determined  on  a  rational  basis.  For  example,  all  factory  overhead 
cannot  be  charged  against  domestic  sales.  The  direct  costs  of  selling 
and  distribution  in  the  domestic  market  must  be  charged  against 
domestic  sales  and  the  same  procedure  followed  for  export  selling 
costs.  Furthermore, '  general  administration  overhead  must  be  di- 
vided on  a  reasonable  basis. 

In  the  case  histories,  it  will  be  indicated  whether  the  business  or- 
ganizations have  actual  profit  and  loss  statements  prepared  separately 
for  domestic  and  export  sales.  Where  the  profitability  of  export  and 
domestic  sales  are  not  computed  separately  the  comparison  that  will 
be  offered  represents  the  best  judgment  of  the  management.  It 
should  also  be  added  that  when  a  case  is  noted  as  not  preparing  sepa- 
rate profit  statements  for  domestic  and  export  sales,  it  only  means 
that  the  profitability  is  not  measured  in  the  manner  indicated  above. 
The  company  may  keep  its  records  in  some  other  form  not  suited  to 
the  needs  of  this  study. 

The  distribution  of  the  76  cases  among  the  three  groups  and  13 
types  of  price  policies  is  shown  in  Table  1.  The  explanation  of  the 
various  types  of  price  policies  is  given  in  the  text  of  this  chapter. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Table  1 


31 


Name  of  case 

"5 

S 

s 

1 

is 

n 

i"T3 

is  <a 

SB'S 

^  i 

2  o  « 

o  » 
£^ 

is 

til 

X  rt  w 

H 

V  o 
.2  ft 

|9 
s§ 
c  a 

o 

a 

t 

X 

.3 

Ms 

ill 

S  3  S 

1"" 

Group  I.  Export  prices  higher  than  domestic  prices 

9 

5 

8 

0 

Type  1.  Export  monopoly ^ 

2 

3 
4 

21 

2 

3 
0 

0 

2 

1 
4 

2 

3 
4 

Type  .2.  No  standard  export  price;  accept  export  business 
only  when  price  is  equal  to  or  above  domestic  price 

Type  3.  List  prices  for  export  higher  than  domestic  prices 

Group  II.  Export  prices  equal  to  domestic  prices 

10 

2 

13 

2 

4 

Type  4.  Market  price  plus  distribution  costs  for  all  customers- 

4 

1 

16 

0 

0 
0 

4 

1 

5 

..._.. 

4 

1 
8 

Type  5.  Factory  price  plus  distribution  costs  for  all  types  of 
customers ..  .  . 

Type  6.  One  price  policy  for  all  customers 

2 

4 

Group  III.  Export  prices  lower  than  domestic  prices 

46 

45 

32 

6 

4 

31 

6 

Type  7.  Standard  export  price  same  as  domestic,  but  conces- 
sion given  in  some  markets  - . 

8 
7 
6 

15 

1 
6 
3 

8 
7 
5 

15 

1 
6 
3 

3 
6 
4 

15 

1 
3 

3 

r 
1 

1 

1 
1 

2 

1 
4 
4 

12 

1 
6 
3 

4 

Type  8.  Export  business  with  different  type  of  customers 
than  domestic,  but  concession  given  in  some  markets 

Type  9.  Standard  export  prices  lower  than  domestic  prices  for 
some  commodities _ 

I 

Type  10.  Domestic  and  export  sales  departments  establish 
prices  independently  on  basis  of  factory  costs  plus  distri- 
bution costs;  some  concessions  in  export 

Type  11.  All  foreign  sales  made  by  company  affiliates;  con- 

Type  12.  All  foreign  sales  made  at  lower  than  domestic  prices. 

Type  13.  Export  agents  and  commission  houses 

Total  number  of  cases 

76 

50 

50 

17 

17 

33 

9 

GROUP  I.  CASES  OF  HIGHER  EXPORT  THAN"  DOMESTIC  PRICES 

Out  of  the  total  of  76  cases,  9  were  found  to  have  higher  export 
than  domestic  prices  for  either  a  significant  part  or  for  all  export  sales 
and  to  have  no  class  of  export  business  on  which  prices  were  lower  than 
domestic  prices  for  a  similar  class  of  customer.  That  is,  in  these 
9  cases,  after  invoice  prices  are  adjusted  for  differences  in  terms  and 
conditions  of  sale  or  for  significant  differences  in  selling  costs,  export 
prices  are  higher  than  domestic  for  at  least  a  part  of  export  sales 
and  no  less  than  equal  to  domestic  prices  for  the  remainder  of  export 
sales.  Of  necessity,  export  business  as  a  whole  is  more  profitable  than 
domestic  in  all  these  cases. 

Type  1.  Export  Monopoly. 

The  distinguishing  characteristic  of  export  price  policy  in  cases 
of  group  I,  type  1  is  that  export  prices  are  admittedly  monopoly  prices 
regardless  of  the  competitive  or  noncompetitive  nature  of  domestic 
prices.  The  United  States  producers  account  for  a  dominant  share 
of  world  production.  In  the  cases  of  this  type  which  fell  in  our 
sample,  they  (or  most  of  them)  have  organized  an  export  corporation 
under  the  Webb-Pomerene  Act  which  enables  them  to  agree  upon  and 
fix  export  prices.  Thus,  control  over  a  major  portion  of  world  supply 
is  the  economic  factor  which  dominates  export  pricing  policy.    Two 


22  OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

cases  out  of  tlie  9  in  group  I  were  of  this  type.  A  case  of  this  type 
is  described  in  the  following  example: 

Example  1. — This  company  produces  various  qualities  of  a  single 
chemical  product  of  which  the  United  States  is  the  predominant  source 
of  world  supply.  The  bulk  of  the  output  is  sold  direct  to  large  indus- 
trial users  in  both  domestic  and  export  markets  in  carload  lots  while 
smaller  quantities  are  parcelled  out  to  dealers  or  smaller  users  from 
regional  warehouses. 

In  the  domestic  market  the  company  sells  carload  lots  on  an  f .  o.  b. 
factory  basis  at  a  uniform  price  to  all  buyers  of  that  quantity.  To 
its  export  customers  the  company  always  quotes  c.  i.  f.  prices  which 
are  substantially  the  c.  i.  f.  prices  established  by  a  Webb-Pomerene 
export  corporation  representing  most  of  the  industry  but  of  which 
the  company  interviewed  is  not  a  member.  The  c.  i.  f.  export  prices 
have  been  set  according  to  a  zone  or  regional  system  with  differentials 
corresponding  in  part  to  the  larger  differences  in  ocean  freight  costs 
which  are  included  in  the  c.  i.  f.  price,  but  also  giving  those  regions 
which  contain  the  larger  industrial  users  a  somewhat  lower  price. 
Within  any  region,  however,  and  as  among  the  several  regions  the 
ocean  freight  costs  from  the  usual  port  of  export  from  the  United 
States  do  not  vary  identically  with  the  c.  i.  f.  prices.  The  company, 
therefore,  sells  abroad  at  any  one  time  at  a  number  of  f.  o.  b.  mill 
prices. 

These  f.  o.  b.  mill  export  prices  are  all  higher  than  the  f.  o.  b.  mill 
domestic  price.  On  the  average  the  mill  net  or  export  sales,  less  the 
extra  costs  of  export  packing,  is  about  20  percent  higher  than  the 
domestic  price. 

The  management  states  that  in  its  experience  selling  costs  for  export 
business  are  a  little  higher  than  for  the  domestic  market  and  export 
credit  terms  must  be  adjusted  to  the  greater  distances  involved.  How- 
ever, export  business  is  still  considerably  more  profitable  than  domestic. 

Example  2. — One  other  case  in  the  sample  was  of  this  general  type, 
also  involving  a  single  chemical  product.  It  might  be  well  to  give 
a  description  of  the  price  policy  m  this  case  also,  so  that  the  reader 
can  observe  the  individual  differences  in  price  policies  among  various 
cases,  even  though  classified  as  being  of  the  same  type.  The  Ameri- 
can industry  in  this  case,  while  the  major  source  of  world  supply,  doies 
not  possess  a  large  enough  share  of  world  output  to  dictate  world 
prices,  but  prices  in  foreign  markets  are  fixed  through  agreements 
with  the  important  foreign  producers. 

The  enterprises  involved  include  a  Webb-Pomerene  export  corpora- 
tion and  the  several  domestic  producing  companies  which  own  its 
stock.  The  domestic  producing  companies  sell  only  in  the  domestic 
market,  while  the  export  corporation  sells  only  in  foreign  markets. 
This  commodity  is  sold  in  the  domestic  market  at  uniform  delivered 
prices,  and  as  the  freight  costs  to  various  destinations  differ  there  are 
a  variety  of  f.  o.  b.  prices.  Export  prices  are  always  quoted  c.  i.  f. 
and  have  been  set  with  small  differences  from  one  geographical  area 
to  another.  These  c.  i.  f.  prices  are  much  more  similar  than  would  be 
the  case  if  actual  insurance  and  freight  costs  for  each  shipment  were 
added  to  a  uniform  f.  o.  b.  or  f .  a.  s.  price  as  there  has  been  a  conscious 
attempt  to  approximate  a  uniform  delivered  price,  equalizing  the  price 
to  foreign  buyers  who  are  in  competition  with  each  other.    Therefore, 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  33 

on  an  f.  o.  b.  basis,  export  prices  too  differ  for  almost  every  point  to 
which  shipment  is  made. 

The  export  corporation  pays  all  the  expenses  connected  Avith  the 
export  business  and  turns  over  the  net  receipts  from  sales  to  the  pro- 
ducing companies.  Likewise,  the  producing  companies  pay  all  the 
costs  of  domestic  distribution.  Costs  are  higher  for  export,  even 
deducting  freight  costs  in  both  cases,  because  selling  and  other  costs  are 
higher  on  the  export  business. 

It  would,  therefore,  be  inappropriate  to  compare  the  whole  scale  of 
f.  o.  b.  domestic  prices  with  the  whole  scale  of  f.  o.  b.  export  prices. 
Furthermore,  as  there  is  discrimination,  in  a  sense,  involved  in  selling 
at  uniform  delivered  prices  in  both  domestic  and  export  markets  it  is 
the  average  net  realization  on  domestic  and  export  business  which  must 
be  compared  rather  than  the  net  realizations  for  individual  transac- 
tions. Of  course,  production  costs  per  unit  of  outpiit  must  be  consid- 
ered the  same  regardless  of  destination. 

The  producing  companies  in  this  case  report  that  the  average  net 
realization  (or  the  net  price  in  our  sense)  is  somewhat  higher  on  export 
sales  than  on  domestic  sales. 

Type  2. 

No  standard  export  price ;  accept  export  business  only  when  price  is 
equal  to  or  above  domestic  price.  Export  price  policy  in  the  cases  of 
this  type  can  be  described  as  follows:  Export  prices  are  quoted  on  a 
c.  i.  f.  basis.  Foreign  sales  involve  higher  costs  than  domestic  busi- 
ness— apart  froni^ansportation  costs — for  such  items  as  export  pack- 
ing, special  handling,  longer  credit  terms,  larger  selling  commissions, 
etc.  Furthermore,  there  is  no  standard  or  list  export  price,  but  prices 
are  quoted  for  almost  each  transaction  as  the  business  is  of  that  char- 
acter. Export  business  is  not  accepted  at  u  c.  i.  f.  price  which  does  not 
cover  all  the  added  costs  of  export  and  yield  a  net  at  least  as  high  or 
higher  than  its  domestic  price. 

Three  cases  with  entirely  unrelated  products  were  found  to  have 
a  price  policy  of  this  type.  In  fairness  to  the  concerns  involved  the 
products  are  not  described  very  specifically  in  order  to  avoid  disclosing 
information  to  competitors.  Suffice  it  to  say  that,  in  general  terms, 
the  products  of  the  three  concerns  respectively  are  a  silk  textile  prod 
uct,  a  wood-pulp  product,  and  a  related  group  of  chemical  products. 
The  following  example  is  illustrative  of  the  cases  of  this  type : 

Example  3. — This  firm  produces  a  wood-pulp  product  that  is  sold 
to  industrial  consumers  for  further  fabrication — craft  board  for  ship- 
ping containers.  In  the  domestic  market  the  company  sells  directly  to 
manufacturers  at  a  uniform  delivered  price.  Prices  are  generally  an- 
nounced quarterly  and  contracts  drawn  to  cover  the  business  for  the 
coming  quarter.  It  is  A^ery  seldom  that  prices  are  changed  during  the 
quarter. 

Its  export  sales  are  made  through  commission  agents  on  a  c.  i.  f. 
oasis.  There  is  no  fixed  price  for  export  as  the  price  is  always  reached 
by  negotiation  between  the  company  and  the  customer  through  the 
agent.  As  the  mill  is  located  on  tidewater  there  is  no  inland  freight 
on  export  shipments  but  there  are  extra  costs  for  export  packing, 
agent's  commission,  ocean  freight  and  insurance,  handling  documents, 
rabies,  etc.     The  management  will  not  confirm  a  c.  i.  f.  price  wliioh 


34  OONCENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER 

does  not  at  least  cover  these  costs  for  the  shipment  plus  the  average 
net  realization  (average  1  o.  b.  price)  on  domestic  sales.  But  it  often 
obtains  export  orders  at  prices  higher  than  this  minimum. 

At  the  present  time  the  company  is  exporting  approximately  10  per- 
cent of  its  output  to  various  customers  in  five  foreign  countries  at  a 
different  f.  o.  b.  price  in  almost  each  case.  The  lowest  is  just  about 
equal  to  the  average  f,  o.  b.  mill  realization  on  domestic  sales  while 
the  spread  from  the  highest  export  price  to  the  lowest  is  roughly  16 
percent.  On  the  average,  export  prices  on  an  f.  o.  b.  basis  are  7-8 
percent  higher  than  the  average  domestic  net  realization. 

Type  3. 

List  prices  for  export  higher  than  domestic  prices.  One  other  type 
of  price  policy  was  found  among  the  cases  having  higher  export  than 
domestic  prices.  The  remaining  four  cases  in  group  I  were  all  of  this 
type,  involving  producers  of  electrical  products — radio  receiving  sets 
and  electrical  refrigerators. 

For  group  I,  type  3,  products  are  sold  from  price  lists  which  are 
identical  for  all  customers  in  the  domestic  market  of  the  same  class; 
that  is,  all  distributors  or  wholesalers  or  retailers,  etc.,  are  issued  the 
same  price  list  and  all  sales  are  made  at  the  prices  shown  thereon.  The 
same  procedure  is  used  in  export  markets.  Export  price  lists  are 
issued  and  all  sales  are  made  according  to  those  prices.  While  the 
prices  on  the  export  price  sheet  may  be  the  same  as  those  on  the  do- 
mestic price  sheet  for  a  few  items,  for  most  items  or  models  the  export 
price  is  higher.  These  differentials  in  list  prices  are  not  related  to 
differences  in  costs.  In  fact,  in  those  instances  where  clear  answers 
could  be  obtained,  distribution  costs  on  export  business  were  lower 
than  on  domestic  business.  The  following  example  is  illustrative  of 
cases  of  this  type. 

Example  If.. — The  products  in  this  case  are  radio  receiving  sets  and 
radiophonograph  combinations  in  a  wide  variety  of  styles  and  models. 
The  company  also  manufactures  other  lines  of  products  which  have 
entirely  distinct  uses  and  which  are  sold  by  distinct  merchandising 
departments.  As  the  price  policies  for  the  different  lines  of  products 
are  entirely  unrelated,  the  radio  department  of  the  company  is  con- 
sidered here  as  a  separate  case  for  the  sake  of  clarity. 

In  the  domestic  market  the  products  are  sold  only  to  wholesale  dis- 
tributors from  a  uniform  price  list  f.  o.  b.  factory.  The  domestic 
business  is  a  package  business;  that  is,  there  is  no  adaptation  of  the 
product  itself  to  fit  the  peculiar  requirements  of  the  wholesaler.  There 
IS  a  wide  variety  of  models  to  fit  the  needs  and  purchasing  power  of 
the  consumer  but  all  the  units  of  a  particular  model  are  exactly  the 
same  and  they  are  all  sold  complete  and  packaged  just  as  they  come 
off  the  assembly  line. 

A  large  part  of  the  export  business  is  of  a  different  character  and 
many  complications  arise  because  the  products  must  be  adapted  to 
meet  the  special  requirements  of  many  markets.  In  the  first  place,  a 
line  of  export  models  not  sold  in  the  domestic  market  is  produced  to 
fit  the  reception  conditions  existing  in  many  foreign  markets.  But 
even  the  same  models  which  are  sold  in  the  domestic  market  must 
often  be  adapted  for  the  export  trade.  These  adaptations  are  of  two 
kinds,  physical  and  ecorremic.  The  physical  are  required  primarilv  to 
meet  different  voltages  tliaii  those  standard  in  the  United  States,  while 


I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  35 

the  economic  adaptations  are  required  to  meet  the  peculiarities  of  tariff 
laws  country  by  country.  Because  of  tariff  laws,  often  designed  to 
encouraofe  some  part  of  the  manufacture  or  assembly  being  performed 
locally,  shipment  must  be  made  in  all  manners  of  special  packaging 
and  various  stages  of  assembly.  For  example,  it  may  be  necessary,  in 
order  to  avoid  a  duty  of  prohibitive  cost,  to  ship  the  receiving  set 
without  cabinet  and  allow  the  foreign  distributor  to  procure  cabinets 
locally;  to  ship  tubes  in  a  separate  package;  to  ship  only  the  major 
parts  and  to  have  the  assembly  clone  locally;  certain  parts  made  of  or 
containing  metals  dutiable  at  a  higher  rate  may  have  to  be  excluded 
or  shipped  separately,  etc.,  in  an  endless  variety.  Nevertheless,  a  con- 
siderable portion  of  the  exports  are  shipped  right  from  the  assembly 
line,  just  as  in  the  domestic  market. 

INIuch  of  the  export  business,  therefore,  requires  special  pricing 
either  because  there  is  no  correspondirg  model  sold  in  the  domestic 
market  or  because  manufacturing  costs  are  lower  or  higher  through 
the  exclusion  of  certain  parts  or  through  the  complicated  special  pack- 
aging that  is  needed.  The  management  states  that  on  all  this  business 
the  gross-profit  margin — that  is,  the  difference  between  factory  costs 
and  price — is  higher  than  the  gross-profit  margin  on  domestic  business. 
This  mears,  in  terms  of  the  concepts  useful  for  our  problem,  that 
export  prices  on  this  class  of  business  are  higher  than  domestic  prices 
for  dissimilar  but  comparable  commodities. 

The  remaining  export  sales  are  made  from  standard  export  price 
lists.  A  part  of  this  business  also  requires  special  packaging,  and 
while  this  does  increase  factory  costs,  the  increase  is  too  small  to  be 
added  to  the  price  and  is  merely  offered  as  an  accommodation  to  the 
customer.  But  a  significant  share  of  export  sales  are  of  products 
identical  with  those  sold  in  the  domestic  market.  A  comparison  of 
domestic  and  export  prices  to  distributors  shoAvs  the  export  pi-ices  to 
be  almost  corsistently  higher  from  about  50  cents  to  $3  per  set.  The 
avorage  differential  between  the  list  prices  for  export  and  domestic 
sale  is  about  3  percent.  The  price  difference  is  not  a  specific  adjust- 
ment for  any  difference  in  costs  but  is  an  arbitrary  addition  to  the 
domestic  price. 

Certain  other  differences  between  domestic  and  export  price  policy 
.should  be  noted.  Domestic  sales  are  f.  o.  b.  factory  while  export  are 
f.  a.  s.  The  inland  freight  costs  are  quite  small  but  they  are  absorbed 
by  the  company.  The  domestic  distributor  is  given  a  specified  ad- 
vertising allowance  which  appears  on  the  domestic  price  list,  for  each 
set  purchased  but  such  automatic  allowances  are  not  granted  to 
export  customers.  The  company,  howe^'er,  gives  specific  allowances 
where  the  market  requires  or  justifies  the  expenditure.  The  export 
customer  is  given  a  small  quantity  discount  for  volume  purchases  in 
order  to  induce  larger  shipments,  but  domestic  prices  are  not  sub- 
ject to  a  quantity  discount.  Credit  terms  in  export  are  adjusted  to  the 
longer  distances  involved.  If  list  prices  could  be  adjusted  for  all 
these  differences  it  is  hardly  likely  that  the  relationship  of  domestic 
and  export  prices  would  be  changed. 

In  order  to  fully  adjust  prices,  however,  account  must  be  taken 
of  the  difference  in  selling  costs.  The  management  reports  that  sell- 
ing costs  in  the  domestic  market  are  proportionately  much  hig\ii^ 

25776&— 41 — No.  0 3 


3g  CONCENTRATION  OF  EGONOMIO  POWER 

than  on  export  sales.  The  company's  expenditure  for  advertising, 
salesmen,  and  field  representatives  is  much  lower  abroad.  Thus  the 
difference  in  prices  adjusted  for  all  differences  in  costs  would  be  sub- 
stantially greater  than  the  3  percent  difference  in  list  prices. 

Accounting  records  are  kept  separately  of  the  net  profit  margin 
on  domestic  and  export  sales  and  it  is  consistently  higher  on  exports. 
In  fact,  in  many  recent  years  the  domestic  sales  department  has  shown 
an  operating  loss  while  the  export  department  has  earned  a  profit. 

In  the  other  three  cases  of  this  type  there  are  no  essential  dif- 
ferences from  the  facts  in  the  above  example  with  regard  to  price 
policy  or  profit  comparison. 

GROUP  n.   CASES  OF  EXPORT  PRICES  EQUAL  TO  DOMESTIC  PRICES 

In  21  cases  out  of  the  total  sample  of  76,  export  prices  were  equal  to 
domestic  prices.  It  is,  nevertheless,  possible  to  distinguish  several 
types  of  price  policies  or  pricing  methods  among  these  cases.  When  in- 
voice prices,  however,  are  adjusted  for  the  specific  cost  items  repre- 
sented in  different  terms  and  conditions  of  sale  it  is  found  that  the  basic 
prices  are  the  same  whether  the  sale  is  domestic  or  foreign.  The 
profit  experience  in  these  cases  also  differs  between  the  net  profit  on 
domestic  sales  as  a  whole  and  export  sales  as  a  whole.  It  will  be 
recalled  that  this  comparison  of  net  profits  can  measure  differences 
in  the  costs  of  doing  business  which,  from  a  business  standpoint, 
cannot  be  taken  into  account  in  price  making.  Since  these  are  not 
significant  cost  differences,  the  profit  differences  are  not  substantial. 

Type  4. 

Market  'price  plus  distribution  costs  for  all  (mstomers. — The  first  type 
of  price  policy  in  this  group  was  found  to  be  followed  by  four  cases 
(each  a  separate  firm  or  group  of  firms)  in  which  the  products  were 
standardized  or  accurately  graded  commodities.  These  commodities 
have  prices  which  fluctuate  from  day  to  day  according  to  conditions 
of  the  market  or  according  to  the  fluctuations  of  a  basic  raw  material 
quoted  on  an  organized  commodity  exchange.  The  firms  in  these  four 
cases  were  processers  of  packing-house  products,  flour-mill  products, 
canned  fruits  and  vegetables,  and  certain  dairy  products,  respectively. 

While  these  products  bear  the  name  of  the  producer,  the  brand  is 
relatively  unimportant  in  the  price-making  process  on  wholesale  busi- 
ness. The  buyers  are  well  acquainted  With  the  market,  they  always 
have  alternative  sources  of  supply,  and  they  buy  according  to  specifi- 
cation, grade,  or  sample.  The  buyer  almost  always  asks  for  a  quota- 
tion which  includes  delivery  to  his  establishment  but  he  always  has 
the  alternative  of  buying  f.  o.  b.  the  processing  establishment. 

In  these  cases  there  is  no  essential  distinction  between  domestic 
and  export  business.  The  company  sells  only  at  the  market  price  and 
while  price  quotations  are  made  by  salesmen  in  the  various  domestic 
and  foreign  sales  division  for  all  sorts  of  terms  and  conditions  of  sale 
all  these  quotations  are  based  upon  the  f.  o.  b.  market  price  at  the 
processing  establishment.  As  accurately  as  they  can  be  calculated,  the 
exact  costs  involved  in  any  sale  on  any  other  than  f .  o.  b.  factory  cash 
basis  are  computed  and  added  to  the  f.  o.  b.  price  to  arrive  at  the 
delivpred  ]iricH.     Most  price  quotations  are  not  made  f.  o.  b.  factory 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  37 

but  (e.  g.)  f.  o.  b.  cars  in  New  York  or  other  United  States  cities; 
f.  a.  s.  New  York  or  San  Francisco,  payment  against  documents; 
c.  i.  f .  some  foreign  port,  payment  on  first  presentation  of  papers ;  etc. 
But  in  eacli  case  the  domestic  or  export  sales  division  or  branch  must 
calculate  the  costs  involved,  including  selling  expenses  on  that  type  of 
business,  so  that  the  f .  o.  b.  net  at  the  processing  establishment  will  be 
equal  to  the  market  price  on  that  day. 

The  firms  in  these  cases  are  engaged  primarily  in  a  staple  com- 
modity business  and  the  price  policy  conforms  more  precisely  than 
any  other  cases  in  the  sample  to  the  picture  described  as  existing 
under  conditions  of  pure  competition  where  there  is  narrow  differen- 
tiation of  functions.  The  cost  of  each  function  or  service  is  computed 
as  accurately  as  possible  and  any  service  rendered  on  a  particular  sale 
is  reflected  in  the  invoice  price  at  which  that  sale  is  made.  The 
company's  profit  is  made  in  the  processing  of  the  product,  and  details 
of  distribution  are  on  a  cost  basis.  Each  sales  branch  or  division 
needs  only  cover  its  costs  plus  the  market  price  of  the  product. 

This  description  of  the  price  policy  is  not  meant  to  imply  that 
the  net  return  on  every  single  transaction  at  a  particular  time  is 
exactly  equal.  The  marketing  process  cannot  function  with  such 
accuracy.  But  the  fluctuations  above  and  below  the  market  price  are 
in  the  nature  of  random  fluctuations  and  not  due  to  conscious  policy. 
It  might  be  said  that  these  differences  are  due  to  imperfections  of 
the  market  and  uncertainties  as  to  the  actual  cost  of  a  particular  func- 
tion. There  is  no  distinction  in  this  regard  between  domestic  and 
export  sales.  For  all  practical  purposes  domestic  and  export  business 
are  equally  profitable. 

In  several  of  these  cases  the  producers  also  market  highly  adver- 
tised branded  products  more  or  less  similar  to  those  sold  as  com- 
modities. Although  costs  are  higher,  the  profit  margin  is  larger  for 
the  branded  than  for  the  commodity  business  in  the  domestic  market. 
These  branded  products  are  seldom  exported  as  there  is  no  demand 
abroad  for  justifying  the  existing  differential  over  similar  nonbranded 
products.  The  small  export  shipments  appear  to  be  for  the  use  of 
Americans  residing  abroad  and  are  made  at  domestic  prices. 

It  might  be  noted  that  the  profit  margin  on  sales  in  these  cases  is' 
quite  small  and  general  overhead  is  not  a  large  proportion  of  total 
costs  in  comparison  with  many  manufacturing  firms.  Thus  almost 
every  item  of  expense  is  a  significant  item  from  a  business  standpoint 
and  cannot  be  neglected  in  making  a  price  quotation. 

Type  6. 

Factory  price  plu-s  distribution  costs  for  all  customers. — This  type 
of  price  policy  is,  from  outward  appearances,  similar  to  type  4.  It 
varies  in  that  the  price  is  not  established  by  some  organized  market, 
but  the  basic  f.  o.  b.  mill  prices  of  the  company's  products  are  set  by 
the  administrative  and  production  officers.  These  internal  prices  in- 
clude profit  and  all  cost  items  except  selling  and  distribution  expenses. 
These  mill  prices,  which  are  issued  confidentially  to  the  various  sales 
departments,  include  factory  costs,  designing,  general  administrative 
overhead,  and  profit.  The  various  sales  departments  of  the  company, 
each  of  which  serves  a  different  type  of  customer,  are  charged  by  the 
mill  at  the  mill  prices  and  establish  the  prices  to  their  customers  so 


Qo  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

as  to  cover  the  mill  price  plus  the  actual  selling  and  distribution  ex- 
penses of  their  department.  The  essence  of  this  price  policy  is  that 
the  various  sales  departments  are  not  expected  to  show  a  profit  above 
mill  price  plus  departmental  expenses  as  the  company's  profit  is  al- 
ready in  the  mill  price.  Thus,  if  the  company  was  only  selling  to  one 
type  of  customer  under  the  same  conditions  and  terms  of  sale,  the 
quoted  prices  to  all  buyers  would  be  exactly  the  same.  But  as  each 
sales  department  sells  to  a  different  type  of  customer  under  widely 
different  terms  and  conditions  of  sale  the  quoted  prices  are  different 
by  the  difference  in  the  costs  of  doing  each  type  of  business.  Each 
sales  department  differs  with  regard  to  salesmen,  rates  of  commission, 
costs  of  samples,  method  of  handling,  freight,  packaging;  require- 
ments, credit  terms,  size  of  orders,  etc.,  and  must  adjust  its  quoted 
prices  to  these  cost  items.  The  export  department  is  on  exactly  the 
same  footing  as  the  various  domestic  sales  departments. 

Example  6. — Only  one  case  in  the  sample  was  found  to  follow  con- 
sistently a  pricing  policy  of  this  type.  It  has  been  segregated  as  a 
distinct  type  because  the  nature  of  the  business  is  so  different  from 
the  four  cases  of  type  4.  The  company  is  a  manufacturer  of  cotton 
and  rayon  piece  goods,  most  of  which  are  subject  to  style  factors.  It 
sells  to  various  types  of  customers  who  require  different  kinds  of  serv- 
ices in  the  way  of  packaging,  credit  terms,  delivery,  sales,  solicitation, 
etc.  The  prices  for  each  type  of  business,  whether  domestic  or  export, 
are  all  built  up  from  an  f .  o.  b.  mill  price  by  the  addition  of  the  cost 
involved  in  doing  that  type  of  business.  The  company's  profit  is 
already  included  in  the  f.  o.  b.  mill  price  so  that  each  sales  depart- 
ment, e.  g.,  manufacturers'  sales,  sales  to  wliolesalers,  to  retailers,  de- 
partment stores,  and  export  is  only  expected  to  cover  its  expenses. 
The  same  system  is  used  if  additional  expenses  for  a  particular  type 
of  business  are  incurred  at  the  mill,  as,  for  example,  for  special  pack- 
aging, doubling  and  rolling,  etc.  Of  course,  there  is  some  variation 
from  year  to  year  between  total  receipts  from  sales  and  total  costs 
(counting  the  mill  price  which  includes  profit  as  a  cost)  for  all  the 
sales  departments.  There  are  some  overhead  items  in  each  depart- 
ment's expenses  which  may  be  more  or  less  covered  according  to 
changing  volume  of  sales.  Such  variations  have  been  quite  small  and 
are  in  any  case  in  the  nature  of  business  risks  rather  than  discrimina- 
tory price  policies. 

Invoice  prices  in  export  are  always  higher  than  domestic  for  similar 
types  of  customers  because  of  the  following  costs;  handling  docu- 
ments, more  clerical  work,  special  packing,  larger  selling  commissions, 
and  longer  terms. 

The  style  factor,  which  is  so  important  in  this  business,  introduces 
a  peculiarity  into  the  sales  and  price  policy.  The  price  at  which  a  new 
pattern  is  offered  must  be  high  enough  to  cover  the  costs  of  designing 
and  engraving  on  the  estimated  volume  of  sales.  But  at  this  high  price 
tliere  may  be  no  demand  for  the  pattern  in  export  markets.  After  the 
demand  in  the  domestic  market  lias  tired  of  the  style  and  the  mill  has 
covered  the  designing  and  engraving  costs  it  may  be  offered  to  export 
customers  at  a  lower  price.  AVhile  the  mill  would  be  willing  to  sell  at 
this  lower  price  in  the  domestic  market  it  is  often  impossible  to  push 
a  "finished"  number  by  a  similar  moderate  price  reduction.     Where 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  39 

style  is  a  factor  the  customers  want  something  new  and  business  cannot 
be  captured  with  last  season's  patterns. 

Tyfe  6. 

One-price  policy  for  all  customers. — The  remaining  16  cases  of  group 
II  sell  their  products  to  export  customers  at  the  prices  established  for 
the  domestic  market  under  substantially  identical  terms  and  conditions 
of  sale.  For  all  practical  purposes  these  firms  draw  no  distinction 
between  domestic  and  export  customers.  In  some  cases  there  are  slight 
modifications  in  the  terms  and  conditions  offered  to  export  customers, 
but  these  have  been  introduced  to  simplify  business  operations  and  can 
hardly  be  considered  discriminations.  Essentially  the  company  fixes  a 
price  for  its  products,  with  or  without  such  supplementary  services  as 
credit  terms^  packaging,  free  delivery  in  the  United  States,  etc.,  and 
sells  to  all  its  customers  at  those  prices.  The  only  distinction  that 
cculd  be  drawn  between  domestic  and  export  selling  terms  is  that  in 
most  of  these  cases  arrangements  for  payment  by  export  customers  are 
adjusted  to  fit  the  greater  distances  involved  and  the  special  credit 
instruments  customary  in  export  practice.  In  none  of  these  cases  are 
long  credit  terms  granted  in  export  in  lieu  of  a  price  concession  nor  is 
the  longer  wait  for  payment  on  export  business  a  significant  cost  item 
to  the  company. 

Prices  in  these  cases  may  be  adjusted  by  the  company  for  special 
manufacture,  special  packing,  for  freight  and  insurance  on  c.  i.  f .  bill- 
ings, etc.,  but  these  things  are  all  done  for  the  convenience  of  the  cus- 
tomer who  has  the  option  of  buying  the  standard  product  in  the  stand- 
ard waj-  at  the  standard  price.  In  fact,  in  most  cases  additions  to  the 
standard  price  for  such  additional  costs  are  almost  always  shown  on 
the  invoice  at  cost. 

In  all  these  cases  selling  expenses  are  subsummed  under  the  general 
costs  of  doing  business  and  prices  are  never  adjusted  for  differences  in 
actual  selling  costs  from  one  locality  to  another  even  where  the  records 
are  kept  so  as  to  show  the  difference.  The  company  employs  the  num- 
ber of  salesmen  it  needs  to  handle  the  business,  pays  the  commissions 
required  to  get  the  type  of  representation  it  desires,  advertises  in  what- 
ever volume  it  sees  fit  or  not  at  all  if  the  size  of  the  market  does  not 
justify  an  expenditure,  and  commits  itself  for  any  other  incidental  dis- 
tribution expenses  that  will  get  sales  in  any  locality,  whether  foreign  or 
domestic.  "Whether  selling  and  distribution  expenses  are  higher  or  lower 
on  export  sales  as  a  whole  will  be  indicated  below  by  the  comparison  of 
profits.  It  should  be  recognized,  however,  that  in  none  of  these  cases 
is  the  difference  in  profits  substantial,  that  it  would  be  impracticable 
for  the  company  to  have  different  prices  because  of  it,  and  that  there 
is  no  clear  division  in  a  functional  sense  between  the  company's 
domestic  and  export  business. 

The  16  cases  of  this  type  produced  the  products  indicated  in  the  fol- 
lowing table  which  also  shows  the  comparative  profits  experience  on 
domestic  and  export  business  as  a  whole. 


40 


OGNCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Product 


Is  a  profit  statement 
prepared  separately 
for  export  sales 
which  takes  full 
account  of  all  cost 
items? 


Are  export  sales  more  or  leas 
profitable  than  domestic 
because  of  differences  in 
advertising,  selling,  or  inci- 
dental costs? 


1.  Women's  hosiery  and  accessories 

2.  Writing;  paper 

3.  Laboratory  apparatus 

4.  Adding  and  calculating  machines 

6.  Adding;  machines ^ 

6.  Adding,    calchlating,    and    bookkeeping   ma 

chines. 

7.  Paper  grocery  specialties 

8.  Men's  fumisnings.-. ...:... 

9.  Pipe  fittings 

10.  Hosiery,  all  kinds 

11.  Automobiles 

12.  Automobiles  and  trucks 

13.  Machine  tools 

14.  Scientific  equipment 

16.  Felt  and  other  hats 

Ifi.  Phonograph  records 


No  difference. 
Do. 
Do. 
Do. 
Do. 
Selling  costs  lower  on  exports, 
therefore    export  sales 
slightly  more  profitable. 
Questionable. 

Exports  somewhat  less  profit- 
able. 
Questionable;  difference 
could  not  be  very  signifi- 
cant. 
Special  case  described  in  ex- 
ample. 

No  difference 

Do. 
No  possible  difference. 
Questionable,  but  not  great 

in  any  case. 
Exports  a  little  less  profit. 

able. 
Exports  more  profitable. 


A  few  examples  of  this  type  of  price  policy  will  be  given  to  show 
the  variety  of  details  and  problems  encountered. 

Example  6. — This  company  manufactures  a  line  of  women's  wear  of 
which  hosiery  is  the  most  important  item.  It  sells  to  retailers  through 
salesmen  in  the  domestic  market  and  through  commission  representa- 
tives in  export  markets  at  the  same  prices  to  all  customers.  There  are 
no  significant  differences  in  costs  for  which,  prices  could  be  adjusted. 
Selling  costs  in  the  domestic  market  are  just  about  the  same  as  com- 
missions paid  in  export  markets ;  advertising  is  about  in  proportion  to 
sales;  the  company  pays  some  freight  on  domestic  business  as  it  sells 
f.  o.  b.  through  sales  offices  but  only  f.  o.  b.  New  York  City  for  exports; 
there  are  a  little  extra  packing  costs  for  export  and  about  a  month 
longer  wait  before  payment  is  received.  The  company  does  not  have 
profit  statements  computed  separately  for  export  business,  but  the 
management  cannot  see  any  reason  for  a  significant  difference  in  the 
proportionate  profitability  of  domestic  and  export  sales. 

Example  7. — A  manufacturer  of  writing  paper  uses  a  zone  price  sys- 
tem in  the  domestic  market  with,  export  prices  equal  to  prices  in  zone  1 
(which  includes  New  York  City) .  A  New  York  exporting  house  rep- 
resents the  company  in  export  business  and  is  paid  a  commission  which 
is  approximately  equal  to  domestic  selling  costs.  Export  business  is 
no  different  to  the  company  than  domestic  business  and  it  sees  no  util- 
ity in  preparing  separate  profit  statements.  It  takes  whatever  busi- 
ness comes,  but  it  cannot  get  much  export  business  under  its  present 
price  policy  as  foreign  competitive  prices  are  generally  lower. 

Example  S. — This  company  is  primarily  a  dealer  in  laboratory  ap- 
paratus and  reagents.  It  manufactures  a  few  specialized  products, 
but  the  great  bulk  of  its  business  is  in  the  distribution  of  the  product 
of  other  manufacturers.  The  main  sales  effort  of  the  company  is 
made  through  a  world-wide  distribution  of  a  large  catalog  and  by 
advertising  in  many  scientific  and  technical  periodicals,  although  there 
is  also  some  direct  solicitation  of  laboratories  by  members  of  the  sales 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  41 

and  technological  staffs.  Most  of  the  business  is  direct  with,  labora- 
tories at  retail  prices  but  it  does  act  as  distributor  for  some  manufac- 
turers and  sells  at  wholesale  to  other  dealers.  The  company  follows  a 
strictly  one-price  policy  in  both  its  retail  and  wholesale  business. 
There  is  no  distinction  of  any  kind  in  its  price  or  selling  policies  be- 
tween domestic  and  export  customers  except  that  it  takes  longer  to 
receive  payments  from  customers  in  more  distant  markets. 

Example  9. — The  products  in  this  case  are  adding,  calculating,  and 
listing  machines.  The  company  has  a  one-price  policy,  but  there  are 
rt  few  distinctions  between  domestic  and  export  customers  designed 
to  facilitate  the  conduct  of  the  business.  Domestic  customers  can  get 
a  slightly  lower  price  for  cash  or  c.  o.  d.  payment.  Exp6rt  customers 
are  only  offered  the  cash  price  with  25  percent  of  value  in  cash  to  ac- 
company the  order  and  the  balance  to  be  paid  on  sight  draft.  This 
arrangement  favors  the  export  customers,  in  that  the  company  absorbs 
the  cost  of  waiting  for  the  balance  of  75  percent,  but  favors  the  domes- 
tic customer  in  that  he  can  buy  on  open  account  if  he  so  desires.  Quan- 
tity discounts  are  offered  the  domestic  trade  on  orders  of  3  to  10  ma- 
chines, but  to  get  the  same  discounts  the  export  customer  must  order  12 
and  24  machines.  The  company  furnishes  advertising  matter  to  its 
domestic  distributors  at  cost  but  does  not  do  so  to  its  export  distribu- 
tors because  of  the  language  difficulties.  On  the  other  hand,  it  sup- 
plies export  packing  without  cost.  The  management  feels  that  all 
these  differences!  are  negligible  in  terms  of  cost  and  that  there  is  no 
difference  in  the  profitability  of  domestic  and  export  business.  - 

Example  10. — This  company  manufactures  a  few  grocery  special- 
ties— toilet  tissue  and  paper  towels.  It  sells  on  a  one-price  policy 
freight  prepaid  anywhere  in  the  United  States  to  domestic  customers 
and  f.  o.  b.  any  port  to  export  customers.  Virtually  the  same  credit 
terms  and  quantity  discounts  are  offered  to  both  domestic  and  export 
customers.  The  company  has  never  considered  any  other  than  a  one- 
price  policy  and  so  has  never  kept  separate  accounting  for  export  busi- 
ness. If  anything,  export  business  is  more  profitable  than  domestic 
because,  (1)  average  freight  costs  are  higher — domestic  business  is 
Nation-wide  whereas  the  bulk  of  exports  leave  from  the  port  of  New 
York  near  which  the  plant  is  located,  and  (2)  advertising  costs  are 
relatively  higher  on  domestic  business.  However,  in  a  few  export 
markets  where  the  products  are  just  being  introduced,  the  development 
expenses  are  very  high  so  that  those  markets  are  not  at  all  profitable 
at  present. 

Example  11. — This  is  a  branded  line  of  men's  wear  of  which  shirts 
and  collars  are  the  major  items.  The  company  sells  direct  to  the 
retailer  through  its  own  salesmen  in  the  domestic  market  and  through 
commission  representatives  in  export  markets.  All  customersr  pay  the 
same  prices  and  the  conditions  of  sale  are  virtually  the  same  except 
that  export  terms  are  somewhat  longer. 

Profit  statements  are  prepared  separately  for  the  export  and  domes- 
tic departments  and  the  company  has  found  that  domestic  business 
is  more  profitable.  It  costs  somewhat  more  to  do  export  business 
because  higher  commissions  are  paid ;  there  is  an  added  cost  in  export 
packing,  and  the  proportionate  costs  of  samples  and  of  advertising  are 
higher. 

Example  12. — The  products  in  this  case  are  black  and  galvanized 
iron  and  brass  pipe  fittings.    Domestic  and  export  price  lists  and  dis- 


42  OONCENTKATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

count  sheets  at  the  present  time  are  identical.  This  is  usually  the 
case  but  as  domestic  discount  sheets  are  issued  more  often  than  export, 
there  is  sometimes  a  temporary  difference  in  net  prices.  Prices  may 
vary  either  way,  export  prices  being  either  slightly  higher  or  lower. 
The  difference  could  not  be  very  great  because  if  a  substantial  change 
were  made  new  lists  would  be  sent  to  both  export  and  domestic 
customers. 

Ai  v^arious  times  the  export  discounts  to  a  particular  country  may  be 
lower  than  the  standard  domestic  and  export  discounts  when  the  com- 
pany is  trying  to  meet  the  price  competition  of  a  foreign  producer  who 
is  trying  to  get  a  foothold  in  the  market.  The  management  states 
that  so  far  as  this  company  is  concerned,  these  situations  are  always 
temporary.  For  if  the  foreign  competitor  continues  the  cut-price  pol- 
icy, the  company  restores  its  standard  prices  and  merely  takes  w^hat- 
ever  of  the  quality  business  it  can  get  under  those  conditions. 

Example  IS.-^This,  case  concerns  a  hosiery  firm  which  has  set  up  a 
subsidiary  company  to  handle  its  export  business.  The  export  com- 
pany has  an  elaborate  selling  organization  which  it  maintains  by  act- 
ing as  export  commission  representative  for  various  related  but  non- 
competing  lines  of  other  domestic  manufacturers.  The  export  com- 
pany sells  at  identical  prices  as  the  parent  hosiery  company. 

Both  the  domestic  sales  department  and  the  export  company  are 
charged  at  somewhat  nominal  figures  (for  bookkeeping  purposes)  for 
all  stocks  they  draw  from  the  factory  warehouse.  Tliey  both  make  a 
profit  over  the  nominal  factory  charges  plus  their  sales  expenses  but 
in  the  case  of  the  export  company  this  includes  the  profit  it  makes  from 
its  commission  business.  The  company  has  no  reason  to  allocate  ex- 
penses specifically  for  the  hosiery  export  business  and  the  management 
was  very  skeptical  that  such  an  allocation  would  have  any  meaning. 
It  could  not  maintain  the  large  export  organization  that  it  does  if  it 
did  not  act  as  export  representatives  for  several  other  firms,  and  it 
coukl  not  handle  its  own  export  business  as  efficiently  as  it  does  if  it 
did  not  have  that  organization.  The  management  ventured  the 
opinion  that  if  the  costs  of  the  export  company  were  distributed  ac- 
cording to  sales  of  the  various  products  (which  it  did  not  think  was 
any  more  reasonable  than  other  possible  allocations),  the  sales  expense 
on  export  business  in  hosiery  would  come  out  higher  than  domestic 
sales  expense  of  the  parent  hosiery  company. 

Example  IJp. — This  case  and  the  one  following  concern  automobile 
manufacturers.  The  first  is  a  company  which  has  no  foreign  branches 
or  affiliated  selling  or  assembly  companies. 

In  the  domestic  markets  the  company  sells  at  two  discounts  from 
its  standard  f,  o.  b.  factory  retail  prices.  The  larger  discount  applies 
to  distributors  on  the  sales  they  make  to  local  dealers  in  their  territory 
while  tlie  smaller  applies  to  sales  that  the  distributors  make  acting  as 
retailers. 

In  export  the  company  makes  no  distinction  between  dealers  and  dis- 
tributors because  it  cannot  exercise  sufficient  supervision  to  use  two 
prices.  It  therefore  sets  the  export  price,  f .  o.  b.  factory,  on  complete 
car  units  approximately  equal  to  the  average  of  the  domestic  prices 
so  that  the  net  return  is  the  same.  All  manufacturing  extras  are  added 
to  the  standard  price,  e.  g.,  heavier  springs,  right  drive,  front  end 
stabilizers,  better  tool  kit,  export  boxing,  etc. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  43 

A  large  part  of  the  export  business  is  in  more  or  less  incomplete 
car  units  due  to  the  specifications  of  foreign  tariff  laws.  Shipments 
are  made  of  parts  for  assembly,  semiknockdown  cars  boxed  for  export, 
less  tires,  inside  upholstery,  bumpers,  or  any  other  parts  or  equipment, 
which  it  may  be  cheaper  for  the  importer  to  purchase  locally.  The 
pricing  policy  of  the  company  for  these  incomplete  car  units  is  to 
compute  the  cost  plus  profit  up  to  the  stage  of  completion  in  which 
shipment  is  made.  The  profit  to  the  company  per  car  would,  there- 
fore, be  less  than  that  secured  on  complete  car  units  but  the  percentage 
of  profit  on  the  dollar  volume  of  sales  would  be  as  nearly  the  same  as 
cost  accounting  methods  can  make  it.  The  company  does  not  compute 
separate  profit  statements  for  domestic  and  export  sales  as  it  sees  no 
reason  to  do  so  since  its  entire  costing  procedure  is  designed  to  give  the 
same  net  return  on  export  sales  as  on  domestic.  The  same  cooperative 
advertising  scheme  is  used  in  export  markets  as  in  domestic  and  the 
ratio  of  other  sales  expenses  could  not  be  much  different. 

The  only  difference  between  domestic  and  export  pricing  policy  is 
that  domestic  terms  are  cash  while  in  a  few  distant  export  markets 
open  accounts  terms  are  extended  up  to  90  days.  The  management 
states  that  the  majority  of  export  sales  are  made  against  letter  of 
credit. 

Retail  prices  in  the  various  export  markets  ai-e  virtually  left  to  the 
discretion  of  the  foreign  distributors  since  they  must  cover  total  landed 
costs  and  be  adjusted  to  local  market  conditions. 

Examvle  15. — This  case  concerns  a  manufacturer  of  automobiles 
and  trucks  havinsr  many  foreiirn  factories,  assembly  plants,  and  sell- 
ing branches.  The  foreign  branches  operate  independently  of  the 
domestic  organization — they  buy  the  products  of  the. parent  company 
according  to  their  specifications  precisely  the  same  and  at  the  same 
prices  as  independent  distributors  buy  them.  The  purpose  of  the 
foreign  subsidiaries  is  to  assure  the  company  of  an  effective  distributive 
agency  in  all  of  the  larger  markets. 

The  pricing  policy  is  virtually  the  same  as  in  the  previous  case. 
Complete  units  have  a  standard  price  f.  o.  b.  factory  from  which  dis- 
counts are  given  to  distributors  and  dealers.  Thf  same  discounts  are 
used  in  exports,  as  the  company  has  found  no  difficulty  in  classifying 
its  foreign  buvers. 

On  incomplete  cars  the  various  production  departments  make  the 
decision  as  to  how  much  will  be  allowed  for  any  deletions.  If  the 
deletions  are  small  they  will  usually  allow  onlv  factory  costs,  thus 
leaving  their  profit  unimpaired.  But  if  the  deletion  is  the  product  of 
another  manufacturer,  for  examnle  tires  or  glass,  they  will  deduct  the 
amount  which  was  originally  added  for  these  parts  and  which  includes 
a  profit. 

The  foreign  branches  of  the  companv  determine  their  own  selling 
prices  upon  the  basis  of  their  total  landed  costs,  assembly  costs,  sales 
expenses,  and  competitive  conditions  in  the  market.  As  all  these 
factors  vary  considerablv  from  country  to  country,  the  profit  earned 
per  car  by  the  foreign  affiliates  varies  widelv,  from  about  $20  to  $200 
on  a  loAv-priced  car  (that  is.  low-priced  in  the  United  State« — in  for- 
eign markets  they  are  usuallv  luxurv  items).  The  volume  of  business 
that  can  be  done  in  a  particular  market  is  the  important  consideration 
in  the  branch's  price  policy.     For  example,  a  country  establishes  a 


44  OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

quota  of,  say,  500  cars  for  this  company  when  its  sales  there  had  been 
averaging  5,000  cars.  The  branch  may  now  be  able  to  get  a  much 
higher  price  for  the  car,  and  the  profit  per  car  may  be  doubled  or 
more  and  yet  the  total  profits  of  the  branch  operations  be  smaller  than 
formerly. 

The  fact  that  the  foreign  branches  earn  a  profit  on  their  operations 
cannot  be  taken  as  evidence  of  a  higher  export  than  domestic  price,  as 
they  perform  additional  functions.  Whether  the  foreign  companies 
are  subsidiaries  or  independently  owned  is  irrelevant  to  tlie  price  com- 
parison so  long  as  equal  treatment  be  accorded  both  types  of  buyers. 

Considering  the  comparative  profitability  of  domestic  and  export 
sales  the  management  states  that  export  is  more  profitable  if  the  opera- 
tions for  the  foreign  companies  are  included,  since  in  export  business 
the  profits  on  some  of  the  distributive  function^  are  included.  But 
from  the  standpoint  of  the  domestic  manufacturing  and  selling  organi- 
zation (which  includes  the  export  department),  there  is  no  consistent 
difference  in  profitability.  There  is  no  difference  on  the  manufactur- 
ing side  because  prices  are  adjusted  to  differences  in  costs.  And  on  the 
distributive  side  the  ratio  of  expense  to  sales  for  the  domestic  and 
export  departments  varies  from  year  to  year  with  the  volume  of  sales 
and  is  not  consistently  larger  in  one  department  or  the  other. 

GROUP  III.   OASES  or  L0"^ER  EXPORT  THAN   DOMESTIC   PRICES 

All  of  the  remaining  case'  fall  into  one  or  another  of  the  types  of 
price  policy  under  group  III,  cases  having  some  export  prices  lower 
than  domestic.  The  reader  will  recall  that  every  case  in  which  some 
export  prices  were  lower  than  domestic  prices  for  similar  goods  to  a 
similar  type  customer,  after  adjustment  for  differences  in  costs,  was 
classified  under  group  III,  except  where  it  was  definitely  a  temporary 
phenomenon.  The  lower  prices  may  apply  to  only  a  few  items  in  a 
wide  and  varied  line  of  products  or  to  only  a  few  foreign  markets  out 
of  a  world-wide  distribution.  Prices  of  other  products  of  the  business 
organization  may  be  higher  than  domestic  prices  and  profits  on  export 
business  as  a  whole  may  be  substantially  greater  than  profits  on  domes- 
tic business.  All  these  facts  will  be  brought  out  in  the  following 
discussion.  But  in  each  of  these  cases  at  least  some  export  sales  are 
made  at  an  actual  price  concession  or  the  equivalent  of  a  price  conces- 
sion in  the  terms  and  conditions  of  sale. 

It  is  worth  noting  at  the  outset  that  in  all  but  one  of  the  cases  in 
group  III  there  is  some  price  variation  from  market  to  market  in  the 
export  business.  That  is,  regardless  of  the  type  of  export  price 
policy,  some  markets  are  being  sold  at  lower  prices  than  other  markets 
for  a  few  or  more  items  that  the  company  manufactures.  Price  vari- 
ation among  export  markets  also  appeared  in  the  first  five  cases  of 
group  I  in  which  export  prices  were  higher  than  domestic  prices.  In 
those  cases  export  prices  were  not  uniformly  higher  to  all  export 
markets  and  in  the  cases  in  group  III  (except  one)  export  prices  are 
not  uniformly  lower  to  all  export  markets. 

Type  7. 

Statidard  export  prices  same  as  doTnesfic  hut  conrrss/otis  given  in 
som-e  markets. — The  first  type  to  be  considered  is  tliat  in  which  the 
basic  export  price  policy,  and  that  which  applies  to  the  bulk  of  the 


C?ONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


45 


export  sales,  is  the  same  as  type  6.  That  is,  these  companies  use  their 
domestic  prices  as  standard  export  prices  and  consummate  a  large 
share  of  their  export  sales  at  those  prices.  However,  in  each  of  the 
eight  cases  in  this  group,  there  are  exceptions — ^to  particular  markets 
or  on  particular  transactions  price  concessions  are  granted.  In  no 
case  was  more  than  20  percent  of  the  export  sales  made  at  prices  below 
the  standard  prices,  so  it  can  be  said  that  the  price  concessions  are 
exceptions  to  the  general  policy  of  selling  domestic  and  export  at  the 
same  prices. 

The  products  in  these  cases  are  given  in  the  following  table.  It  will 
be  noted  that  three  of  these  cases  show  export  business  to  be  a  little 
more  profitable  than  domestic  despite  lower  prices  on  a  portion  of 
exports."  This  is  due  to  the  price  differential  being  offset  by  smaller 
selling  costs  for  exports  as  a  whole. 


Produft 

Export  profits  kept 
separate? 

Export  more  or  less  profitable 

1.  Machine  tools  and  air-conditionin?  equipment. - 

No. 

Questionable 

2.  Extensive  heavy  machinery  line 

No.. 

Do. 

3.  Paper  and  stationery  specialties    

Yes 

Export  slightly  more  profit- 
able. 
Do 

4.  Control  and  measuring  instruments. 

Yes 

5.  Heavy  industrial  chemicals...  ..  

Yes.. 

6.  Brass  plumbing  specialties . 

No 

7.  Cigarettes  and  other  tobacco  products 

No  . 

Do. 

8.  Abrasive  grains. 

No 

Export  slightly  more  profit- 
able. 

Several  examples  are  given  below  for  illustrative  purposes: 

Example  16. — This  company  manufactures  machine  tools,  ventilat- 
ing fans,  and  air-conditioning  equipment.  jMost  of  its  business  is  in 
stock  items,  but  some  is  contract  business  which  is  obtained  by  sub- 
mitting bids. 

The  stock  items  all  have  standard  prices  f.  o.  b.  factory.  As  the 
usual  practice  in  export  is  to  quote  f .  a.  s.  New  York,  the  company  adds 
a  flat  10  percent  to  the  domestic  price  to  cover  the  costs  of  export  pack- 
ing, inland  freight,  document,  etc.  While  these  costs  vary  from  ship- 
ment to  shipment,  the  average  is  about  10  percent,  so  that  this  per- 
centage is  used  to  avoid  numerous  small  calculations.  On  occasion 
however,  when  the  foreign  agent  reports  competition  that  can  be  met 
by  a  moderate  price  concession  the  company  will  absorb  this  10  percent 
co.st  for  f.  a.  s.  billing.  Only  a  small  share  of  the  export  business  is 
subject  to  this  price  concession. 

For  the  contract  business  the  company  has  a  formula  of  the  usual 
labor-materials-and-overhead  type  that  .is  applied  to  determine  the 
pric«  quotation.  But  competition  does  not  allow  the  consistent  use  of 
this  formula.  However,  the  management  states  that  downward  revi- 
sions of  prices  on  this  type  of  business  are  more  frequent  in  domestic 
({notations  than  export,  because  the  company  in  most  instances  is  too 
far  away  from  the  export  market  and  knows  too  little  about  the  com- 
jjetition  there  to  be  able  to  price  specifically  for  it. 

The  company  does  not  have  separate  accounting  for  export  sales, 
and  therefore  does  not  know  how  the  profit  on  export  business  com- 
pares with  domestic.  The  guess  of  the  executive  is,  however,  that 
exports  are  a  little  more  profitable,  as  there  is  proj^ortionately  less 
servicino;  after  a  sale  is  made  and  veiv  little  advertising  abroad.    V>nt 


4g  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

exports  would  definitely  be  much  less  profitable  if  the  10-percent  price 
concession  had  to  be  given  on  all  sales  abroad. 

Example  17. — This  company  manufactures  an  extensive  line  of  paper 
and  stationery  specialties.  It  has  two  price  lists  for  the  domestic  mar- 
ket— one  for  jobbers,  the  other  for  direct  retailer  accounts  purchasing 
$500  or  more  a  year.  Freight  on  domestic  sales  is  absorbed  by  the 
company  except  to  a  few  accounts  in  the  far  west,  where  the  billing  is 
f.  o.  b.  its  Chicago  sales  office.    Terms  are  2  percent  10  days,  net  e.  o.  m. 

Domestic  prices  are  used  for  over  90  percent  of  the  export  sales. 
On  a  small  percentage,  probably  not  over  2  percent,  direct  price  cuts 
are  given  of  from  5  to  15  percent  of  the  domestic  price.  On  another 
small  percentage  of  the  business  the  products  are  not  sold  in  the  same 
form  as  in  the  domestic  market.  In  order  to  reduce  ocean-freight  costs 
or  high  tariff  charges  based  on  gross  Aveight,  the  products  are  shipped 
in  bulk,  unboxed,  or  in  special  light-weight  containers,  and  an  allow- 
ance given  for  the  cartons  or  wrappings  that  must  be  supplied  by  the 
importer.  His  allowance  is  generally  larger  than  the  cost  would  be  to 
the  company  and  the  net  return  on  these  sales  consequently  lower. 

All  export  sales  are  f .  o.  b.  factory  and  terms  net  60  days  after  arrival 
of  the  goods.  The  company  does  not  charge  for  export  packing,  but  it 
limits  direct  accounts  to  those  who  can  purchase  $1,000  or  more  a  year. 

Profits  on  the  export  business  are  kept  separately,  and  consistently 
show  a  somewhat  higher  rate  of  return  on  sales  as  a  whole  than 
domestic.  This  is  due  to  lower  selling  expense,  less  advertising,  and  no 
freight  cost  on  export  sales. 

Example  18. — The  products  in  this  case  are  heavy  industrial  chem- 
icals, predominantly  bulk  materials.  All  sales,  domestic  and  export, 
are  on  a  f.  o.  b.  factory  basis.  In  most  of  the  export  transactions, 
prices  are  identical  with  domestic  prices.  In  some  instances,  how- 
ever, dependent  upon  market  conditions  in  the  particular  country 
involved,  and  upon  the  profit  margin  in  the  particular  product,  price 
concessions  are  offered  to  export  customers  of  as  much  as  8  percent. 
The  management  estimates  roughly  that  the  average  price  of  export 
sales  is  about  3  percent  less  than  for  domestic  sales  for  those  products 
which  are  exported.  Profit  margins  for  many  products  are  so  small 
that  no  concessions  can  be  made  and  most  items  inthe  line  cannot  be 
exported.  Profit  statements  are  prepared  separately  for  export  and 
domestic  business.  Domestic  business  is  consistently  more  profitable 
than  export  due  entirely  to  higher  average  prices.  The  ratio  of 
selling  expenses  to  sales  does  not  differ  materially  between  export  and 
domestic  business. 

Example  19. — This  case  concerns  a  manufacturer  of  tobacco  prod- 
ucts, of  which  only  cigarettes  are  exported.  The  net  price  to  most 
export  markets  is  equal  to  the  domestic  price  less  excise  taxes  and 
dealers'  discount.  On  occasion  price  concessions  are  made  to  markets 
in  which  the  currency  has  depreciated.  The  depreciation  of  a  foreign 
currency  might  also  result  in  a  lower  net  export  price  to  the  company 
because  it  has  been  selling  in  the  foreign  currency  or  because  it  was 
under  contract  to  a  foreign  government  monopoly' to  deliver  its  prod- 
ucts at  a  price  fixed  in  the  foreign  currency.  A  profit  statement  is  not 
computed  separately  for  export  sales,  nor  could  the  executive  estimate 
whether  export  business  was  more  or  less  profitable  than  domestic.  He 
did  not  think  that  the  question  was  very  meaningful  in  view  of  the 
small  volume  of  export  sales. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


47 


The  comparison  of  profitability  of  domestic  and  expoi't  sales  in  these 
cases  represents  a  combination  of  two  factors.  The  first  is  the  lower 
prices  received  on  some  part  of  the  export  sales  which  would,  if  all 
other  things  were  equal,  make  export  business  as  a  whole  less  profit- 
able than  domestic.  The  second  factor  i^  the  relation  of  selling  and 
distribution  costs  on  domestic  and  export  sales  to  the  difference  be- 
tween the  standard  domestic  and  export  prices.  Of  itself,  this  factor 
may  result  in  a  difference  in  the  profitability  of  exports  either  way 
just  as  in  the  cages  of  group  II,  type  6. 

Type  8. 

Export  business  with  different  type  of  customer  than  domec'cic; 
concessions  given  in  some  markets — quite  a  few  firms  in  the  sample 
follow  a  different  method  of  distribution  in  export  markets  than  in 
the  domestic  market.  For  example,  domestic  sales  may  be  only  to 
retailer  or  directly  to  the  consumer,  while  export  sales  are  made  to 
wholesalers  or  exclusive  distributors.  Since  the  company  performs 
more  distribution  functions  in  the  domestic  than  in  export  markets,  a 
lower  invoice  price  to  export  customers  need  not  represent  a  price 
concession. 

The  seven  business  organizations  which  have  been  classified  under 
type  8  all  transact  a  substantial  part  of  their  export  business  with  a 
different  type  of  customer  than  in  the  domestic  market.  Furthermore, 
they  have  a  relatively  standardized  price  differential  between  the  two 
types  of  customers  which,  if  adjusted  for  the  added  costs  of  the  func- 
tions performed  in  the  domestic  market  but  not  in  export  markets, 
does  not  represent  a  price  concession  on  export  sales.  If  all  export 
sales  were  consummated  at  the  company's  standard  export  price,  one 
could  say  that  domestic  and  export  prices  were  equal  and  these  cases 
would  be  in  group  II.  But,  in  each  of  these  cases,  some  part  of  the 
export  transactions  are  made  at  prices  lower  than  the  standard  ex- 
port price,  and  therefore  at  lower  than  domestic  prices.  The  price 
concessions  are  to  particular  countries  to  meet  local  market  conditions. 

These  seven  cases  are  listed  in  the  following  table. 


Product 


Is  a  separate  profit 
statement  prepared 
for  export  sales? 


Is  export  business  more  or  less 
profitable  than  domestic? 


1.  Artificial  teeth... 

2.  Fountain  pens  and  mechanical  pencils 

3.  Safety  appliances 

4.  Panitiiry  napkins  and  cleansing  tissues 

5.  Typewriters. 

6.  Typewriters 

7.  Abrasive  and  refractory  products 


Questionable. 
Export  less  profitable. 

Do. 

Do. 

Do. 
Export  more  profitable. 
No  difierence. 


The  following  examples  are  of  this  type. 

E.rampJe  20. — This  company  manufactures  an  extensive  line  of 
artificiid  teeth.  In  the  domestic  market  its  sales  are  entirely  to  whole- 
salers (dental  depots)  who  in  turn  supply  the  needs  of  the  profes- 
sion— dentists  and  dental  laboratories.  These  wholesalers  carry  the 
products  of  many  manufacturers.  The  promotion  function,  therefore, 
rests  chiefly  upon  the  manufacturer.  It  must  acquaint  the  profession 
with  its  products  and  induce  the  profession  to  order  those  products 
from  the  wholesaler.  In  order  to  do  this,  the  company  advertises  in 
professional  journals,  maintains  exhibits  at  the  conventions  of  the 


4g  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

profession  in  order  to  demonstrate  its  products,  and  canvasses  the 
profession,  individually  and  in  groups.  As  a  consequence,  selling  costs 
are  an  appreciable  item  of  expense,  at  a  rough  estimate  about  25 
percent,  on  the  average,  of  gross  sales. 

In  its  export  business,  the  company  has  two  types  of  selling  pro- 
cedures. For  covering  Europe  and  adjacent  territories,  the  company 
has  appointed  an  exclusive  agent  to  sell  to  wholesalers  and  perform 
all  the  selling  functions  with  the  profession  that  the  company  does 
in  the  domestic  market.  Net  prices  to  this  exclusive  agent  are  about 
30  percent  lower  on  the  average  than  domestic  wholesale  prices.  This 
discount  is  not  the  same  for  all  items  in  the  line  but  varies  from 
approximately  25  to  35  percent,  depending  upon  the  profit  margin 
in  the  item  and  foreign  prices  for  similar  items.  The  management 
was  inclined  to  believe  that  the  net  returns  to  the  company  on  this 
portion  of  export  business  was  on  the  average  somewhat  less  than  the 
net  return  on  domestic  business  when  selling  expenses  in  the  domestic 
market  are  deducted.  However,  an  unqualified  answer  was  difficult 
to  get  because  the  ratio  of  selling  expenses  to  sales  differs  from  year 
to  year  as  the  volume  of  domestic  business  fluctuates.  While  it  cannot 
be  said  that  the  discount  to  the  exclusive  distributor  on  the  whole 
represents  a  price  concession  there  are  price  concessions  in  the  higher 
discounts  given  on  a  few  items  in  the  line. 

The  remainder  of  the  export  business  is  handled  precisely  the  same 
as  domestic;  that  is,  the  company  sells  directly  to  wholesalers  in  the 
various  markets  and  performs  all  the  selling  functions  with  the  pro- 
fession that  it  performs  in  the  domestic  market.  It  advertises  in  the 
local  professional  journals,  prints  catalogs  in  various  foreign  lan- 
guages, and  canvasses  the  profession  in  various  ways  to  acquaint  it 
with  the  products  of  the  company.  Standard  prices  for  this  class  of 
export  business  are  identical  with  domestic  prices  and  the  bulk  of 
the  sales  are  consummated  at  those  prices.  At  the  present  time,  how- 
ever, in  a  few  markets  the  company  is  giving  price  concessions,  aver- 
aging about  5  percent,  due  to  the  fact  that  a  foreign  producer  is 
trying  to  get  a  foothold  in  those  markets. 

The  management  has  never  attempted  to  compute  profit  statements 
separately  for  overall  domestic  and  export  business.  There  is  ap- 
parently some  difference  of  opinion  within  the  organization  as  to 
which  is  the  more  profitable  although  the  executive  interviewed  be- 
lieves that  there  could  not  be  a  significant  difference. 

Exa/mple  21. — The  company  in  this  case  manufactures  a  few  high- 
quality  stationery  items — fountain  pens,  mechanical  pencils,  and  inks. 
In  the  domestic  market  all  sales  are  made  directly  to  the  retailer,  but 
in  export  markets  the  company  has  two  types  of  customers.  In 
Latin  America  and  the  Far  East  the  company's  own  salesmen  deal 
directly  with  the  retailers  at  prices  the  same  as  in  the  domestic  market. 
In  Europe  and  most  other  territories,  the  company  has  appointed 
exclusive  distributors  who  assume  all  local  selling  and  credit  func- 
tions. The  price  policy  of  the  company  in  terms  of  discount  from 
standard  list  prices  is  as  follows:  On  the  direct-to-retailer  business 
there  is  a  slight  difference  between  domestic  and  export  procedure 
designed  to  expedite  the  conduct  of  the  business.  In  the  domestic 
market  the  basic  discount  is  40  percent,  to  which  is  added  quantity 
discounts  on  a  sliding  scale  from  4  to  10  percent  in  proportion  to  the 
volume  of  purchases.    In  exports  on  the  direct-to-retailer  business, 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  49 

the  basic  discount  is  likewise  40  percent.  Instead  of  a  sliding  scale 
of  quantity  discounts,  however,  the  company  offers  an  additional  10 
percent  on  orders  of  12  dozen  or  over  only.  There  is  a  greater  differ- 
ence in  the  price  policy  because  domestic  customers  are  given  cash 
discounts  of  2  percent  while  export  customers  are  given  5  percent  for 
cash  and  2  percent  for  payment  on  first  presentation  of  papers. 

To  its  exclusive  distributors  abroad  the  company  gives  a  basic  dis- 
count of  50  and  10  percent,  but  there  are  some  variations  which  made 
the  discount  slightly  greater  in  a  few  markets. 

The  company  computes  a  separate  profit  statement  for  its  export 
department  and  has  found  that  export  business  is  consistently  less 
profitable  than  domestic.  The  reasons  for  this  are  that  (1)  sales  ex- 
penses in  exports  under  direct-to-dealer  business  are  considerably 
higher  than  in  the  domestic  market,  being  apt  to  run  around  20  per- 
cent of  receipts  in  exports  and  about  10  percent  domestic.  This  is  -due 
to  the  fact  that  more  expensive  type  of  salesmen  must  be  used  in 
export,  travel  abroad  is  more  expensive,  and  advertising  expenditures 
are  larger  abroad  in  proportion  to  volume.  (2)  On  the  exclusive  dis- 
tributor business  the  net  return  to  the  company  is  lower  than  domestic 
sales  receipts  minus  selling  costs.  (3)  Larger  cash  discounts  are  paid 
in  the  export  business  and  the  company  has  to  wait  longer  for  its 
money  on  business  which  is  not  discounted — for  example,  it  takes 
about  5  months  to  get  money  on  a  90-day  sight  draft  from  certain 
distant  points. 

Example  22. — This  case  and  the  one  following  present  an  interest- 
ing contrast  because  of  the  different  results  achieved  by  two  companies 
producing  the  same  commodities  and  following  substantially  the  same 
price  policy.  This  company  manufactures  a  complete  line  of  standard 
and  portable  model  typewriters.  In  the  domestic  market  the  standard 
model  machines  are  sold  direct  to  the  consumer  through  the  branch 
sales  offices  of  the  company  and  by  the  company's  own  salesmen.  The 
bulk  of  the  portable  machines,  on  the  other  hand,  are  distributed 
through  retail  establishments  of  various  types.  Thus  the  standard- 
model  machines  are  sold  by  the  company  only  at  retail  at  well-known 
4ist  prices,  which  are  the  same  throughout  the  nation,  but  from  which, 
liowever,  discounts  are  given  to  large  consumers,  depending  upon  the 
quantity  purchased.  The  portable  machines  are  sold  to  dealers  at 
standard  trade  discounts,  which  do  not  vary  with  quantity. 

In  export  markets  the  company  has  appointed  exclusive  dealers  to 
liandle  all  machines.  Wh'le  the  company  has  field  representatives 
ti-aveliiig  abroad  who  call  on  the  dealers  in  order  to  stimulate  their 
sales  eflforts  and  advise  on  policy,  the  independent  dealers  must  do- 
their  own  advertising  and  bear  all  distribution  and  selling  expenses. 
The  list  prices  used  in  exports  are  slightly  lower  than  the  domestic  list 
prices.  But  as  export  prices  are  all  subject  to  discounts  given  to  the 
dealer,  the  list  prices  are  not  p>articularly  meaningful.  On  standard- 
model  machines  the  discount  given  to  dealers  abroad  varies  somewhat 
from  market  to  market  in  order  to  allow  the  local  dealer  to  meet  the 
competition  existing  in  his  market.  The  range  of  variation  is  approxi- 
mately frCm  40  percent  off  the  export  list  price  to  somewhat  over  50 
percent. 

The  management  has  attempted  to  compute  the  average  net  prices 
received  by  the  company  on  domestic  and  export  sales.  It  finds  that 
the  average  net  received  on  domestic  sales  through  branch  offices,  after 


50 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


deducting  advertising,  commissions,  and  branch  expenses,  is  approxi- 
mately $58,  while  the  average  net  received  on  export  sales  of  an  iden- 
tical machine  would  be  approximately  $55. 

Net  prices  received  by  the  company  on  portable  models  are  more 
nearly  comparable  as  the  bulk  of  the  sales,  both  domestic  and  export, 
are  to  dealers.  Net  export  prices  in  most  instances  are  slightly  le^s  than 
domestic  prices  for  the  higher-price  models  and  slightly  more  than 
domestic  prices  for  the  cheaper  models.  There  are  some  variations 
from  the  standard  export  prices.  In  a  few  niarkets  the  company  is 
getting  higher  prices  on  the  whole  line,  while  in  other  markets  where 
the  competition  is  more  intense,  prices  are  even  lower  than  the  standard 
export  prices. 

The  management  has  separate  profit  and  loss  statements  prepared 
for  export  sales  and  has  found  that  its  export  business  is  less  profitable 
than  domestic.  The  average  net  price  in  the  domestic  market,  less 
all  the  costs  involved  in  direct-to-consumer  business  is  still  higher 
than  the  average  net  price  received  from  export  sales.  In  addition, 
there  are  other  costs  in  export,  which,  while  not  very  great,  still  con- 
tribute to  make  export  business  less  profitable.  For  example,  there  is 
some  special  manufacture  for  export,  the  products  must  be  more 
expensively  packaged,  etc. 

Example  '23. — The  second  company  also  produces  a  complete  line  of 
standard  and  portable  model  typewriters,  as  well  as  other  products 
which  will  not  be  considered  here.  Its  selling  policy  in  the  domestic 
and  export  markets  is  essentially  identical  with  that  of  the  preceding 
case.  It,  too,  has  found  it  necessary  to  give  price  concessions  from 
its  standard  export  discounts  in  order  to  meet  the  encroachment  of 
foreign  competition  which  is  producing  lower  priced  machines. 

The  company  has  separate  profit  and  loss  statements  prepared  for 
its  export  business,  but  in  contrast  to  the  previous  case,  it  has  found 
export  to  be  more  profitable  than  domestic.  The  cost  of  advertising, 
distribution,  selling,  and  the  maintenance  of  branch  offices  are  more 
in  this  case  than  the  difference  between  the  net  price  received  in  the 
domestic  market  and  the  net  wholesale  price  received  on  export  sales. 
The  company  has  virtually  no  advertising  expenses  in  export  and 
selling  costs  are  very  small.  In  addition,  a  considerable  part  of  its 
sales  in  the  domestic  market  are  to  large  users  at  substantial  dis- 
counts. 

Type  9. 

Sfandard  export  prices  loioer  than  domestic  prices  for  some  cotti- 
modities. — The  price  policy  in  the  six  cases  of  this  type  can  be  de- 
scribed as  follows:  The  company  has  standard  export  prices  which 
are  closely  adhered  to  but  their  export  prices  for  at  least  some  of  the 
products  in  the  company's  line  are  lower  than  the  domestic  prices  for 
identical  products.  That  is,  the  standard  net  export  price  is  lower 
than  the  standard  net  domestic  price  for  some  products,  with  full 
consideration  given  to  whatever  differences  in  the  cost  of  doing  busi- 
ness that  there  might  be.  In  two  of  these  cases  export  sales  are  made 
to  a  different  type  of  customer  and  invoice  prices  had  to  be  adjusted 
for  that  fact.  ^ 

The  one  case  of  group  III  which  made  no  exceptions  or  concessions 
from  its  standard  export  prices  is  among  these  six  cases.  In  the  other 
five  cases  there  were  some  special  price  concessions  given  to  par- 


CXDNOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER.  52 

ticular  markets  in  addition  to  the  price  concessions  existing  in  the 
standard  export  prices. 

In  one  case,  a  paint  and  varnish  company,  selling  costs  on  exports 
as  a  whole  are  so  much  lower  than  on  domestic  busmess  that  exports 
are  more  profitable  despite  the  fact  that  standard  export  prices  on 
approximately  21  percent  of  the  items  are  lower  than  domestic  prices. 

The  six  cases  of  this  type  are  shown  in  the  following  table : 


Product 

Are  profits  on  export 
sales  segregated? 

Is  export  business  more  or 
less  profitable? 

1.  Office  supplies. 

2.  Compressors  and  pumps 

Yes 

Export  less  profitable. 
Exports  probably  less  profit- 
able. 

No 

Yes ...- 

Yes 

6.  Stationery  supplies     . 

No 

Yes 

able. 
Exports  less  profitable. 

Export  more  profitable. 

Exojmple  2If. — This  company  manufactures  a  few  items  of  office 
supplies.  In  the  domestic  market  the  company  sells  only  directly 
to  the  consumer  through  its  own  sales  branches  and  traveling  sales- 
men. All  customers  in  the  domestic  market  are  sold  from  the  same 
price  sheet  which  shows  prices  in  a  descending  scale  as  quantity 
purchased  increases. 

In  export  markets  the  company  sells  to  independent  wholesalers 
who  must  assume  the  burden  of  distributing  the  product  to  inde- 
pendent retailers  or  to  the  consumer.  The  domestic  price  sheet  is 
used  for  export  sales,  but  as  these  are  wholesale  transactions  prices 
are  subject  to  a  trade  discount.  The  only  significant  difference  in 
the  cost  of  doing  business,  domestic  and  export,  is  the  maintenance  in 
the  domestic  market  of  the  branch  salesrooms  and  salesmen  which 
perform  the  retail  function.  The  expenses  of  the  sales  branches  and 
of  the  salesmen  attached  to  each  vary  approximately  from  38  percent 
of  sales  to  50  percent,  with  the  average  about  45  percent.  The 
standard  discount  given  in  exports  is  50,  10,  and  5.  Thus,  the 
standard  net  «xport  price  is  lower  than  the  domestic  price  less  average 
selling  expenses.  In  addition,  the  company  gives  somewhat  higher 
discounts  in  a  few  markets  where  competition  is  unusually  intense. 
Profitability  of  export  sales  is  calculated  separately  from  domestic, 
and  consistently  shows  export  business  to  be  less  profitable  than 
domestic,  owing  primarily  to  net  prices  of  exports  being  lower. 

Example  25. — This  company  manufactures  a  few  types  of  ma- 
chinery products  of  which  compressors  and  pumps  are  the  primary 
items.  It  maintains  several  branch  sales  offices  in  the  domestic  mar- 
ket and  also  distributes  through  independent  manufacturers'  repre- 
sentatives. Sales  are  made  eitlier  direct  to  the  consumer  or  to  other 
manufacturers  who  incorporate  the  equipment  in  their  products  re- 
ceiving a  discount  of  15  percent  under  list.  The  company  distributes 
abroad  through  local  commission  representatives.  Its  standard  prii^^ 
for  export  are  identical  with  domestic  prices.  However,  the  billing 
is  f.  a.  s.  New  York  and  includes  export  packing.  These  costs  repre- 
sent a  price  concession  of  about  5  percent. 

The  company  has  never  prepared  comparative  profit  statements 
for  domestic  and  export  business.     Since  the  organization  is  rather 

257769 — 41 — No.  C 5 


g2  OONCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

small  and  exports  only  between  5  and  6  percent  of  its  output,  the 
management  does  not  believe  that  any  extensive  record  keeping  would 
be  justified.  It  estimates  that  in  view  of  the  conimissions  paid  to 
local  agents  and  the  moderate  price  concession  that  is  made  on  export 
sales,  that  export  business  is  slightly  less  profitable  than  domestic. 

Example  26. — The  manufacturing  efforts  of  this  company  are  con- 
centrated upon  two  products  of  stationery  goods.  "Although  the  com- 
pany makes  several  other  products,  they  are  of  minor  importance 
and  are  not  exported.  One  of  its  two  main  products,  which  accounts 
for  the  bulk  of  its  sales,  both  domestic  and  export,  is  produced  to  sell 
in  three  price  classes  for  three  different  types  of  trade.  Only  that 
product  which  in  the  domestic  market  represents  the  highest  price 
class  is  sold  in  export,  as  foreign  prices  for  all  but  first-quality 
goods  in  this  line  are  so  low  that  the  company  cannot  compete  on  a 
price  basis.  In  the  domestic  market  the  company  issues  separate 
price  lists  for  wholesalers  and  retailers,  but  in  export  only  one  price 
list  is  used,  as  the  distinction  between  wholesalers  and  retailers  in 
many  foreign  markets  is  usually  not  clearly  drawn.  From  the  com- 
pany's standpoint,  however,  export  sales  are  comparable  to  sales  to 
wholesalers  in  the  domestic  market.  The  standard  export  price  for 
this  product  is  20  percent  lower  than  the  standard  domestic  price  to 
wholesalers  for  identical  commodities.  In  a  few  markets,  the  com- 
pany is  selling  as  much  as  25  percent  below  its  standard  export  price 
in  order  to  meet  special  temporary  circumstances. 

The  firm's  other  major  product  is  manufactured  to  sell  in  domestic 
markets  in  a  specific  price  class ;  some  models  are  made  to  sell  at  retail 
for  $1  while  other  models  sell  for  $1.50.  The  domestic  prices  to  whole- 
salers are  $6  and  $9  per  dozen,  respectively.  As  the  $1  and  $1.50  prices 
have  no  significance  in  export  markets,  the  company  has  established 
export  prices  of  $7.20  and  $10.80  per  dozen,  respectively,  for  these 
models,  or  a  price  20  percent  higher  than  the  domestic  for  the  largest 
selling  items. 

The  company  has  never  attempted  to  calculate  separate  profit-and- 
loss  statements  for  export  sales.  There  is  no  doubt  in  the  management's 
mind  that  export  business  is  much  less  profitable  than  domestic.  While 
selling  costs  for  export  are  somewhat  lower  than  in  the  domestic  mar- 
ket, they  are  not  sufficiently  lower  to  offset  the  20  percent  lower  price 
received  in  export  on  sales  of  the  firm's  major  product.  In  fact,  the 
management  is  inclined  to  believe  that  the  export  department  was  run 
at  a  loss  before  the  introduction  of  its  new  product  3  years  ago,  for 
which  it  receives  a  higher  price  from  export  customers. 

Type  10. 

Domestic  and  export  sales  departments  establish  prices  independ- 
ently on  basis  of  factory  costs  plus  distribution  costs;  sonne  concessions 
in  export.— -Th^  distinguishing  characteristic  of  pricing  policy  in  cases 
of  this  type  is  that  the  export  and  domestic  sales  departments  are 
operated  as  independent  business  units  and  each  unit  is  completely 
autonomous  over  matters  of  selling  policy  and  price.  It  so  happened 
that  all  the  cases  using  this  type  of  procedure  made  some  of  their 
export  sales  at  lower  than  domestic  prices.  Each  sales  department  is 
charged  by  the  factory  at  factory  costs  (labor,  materials,  and  factory 
overhead)  for  all  orders  it  places.  It  is  also  charged  its  share  of  gen- 
eral administrative  overhead.  It  spends  whatever  it  sees  fit  on  selling 
and  distribution,  and  each  department  fixes  its  own  prices  in  an  effort 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECX>NOMIC  POWER  53 

to  cover  its  cost  items — factory  costSj  administrative  overhead,  and 
department  expenses — and  show  a  pront.  The  point  that  distinguishes 
this  type  of  price  policy  from  type  5  is  that  the  factory  price  does 
not  include  a  profit  so  that  the  various  sales  divisions  are  expected  to 
fix  such  prices  as  will  yield  a  profit  after  all  costs  are  met. 

This  description  is  not  meant  to  imply  that  the  domestic  sales  man- 
ager has  final  responsibility  for  domestic  prices.  The  leading  officers 
of  the  company  are  almost  always  concerned  with  the  determination 
of  domestic  prices.  It  was  found,  however,  that  export  prices  are  gen- 
erally left  to  the  judgment  of  the  export  manager  and  that  he  is  under 
no  obligation  to  consider  domestic  prices  in  any  way  in  fixing  prices 
for  export.  His  obligation  to  the  company  is  to  manage  his  depart- 
ment so  as  to  get  the  volume  of  sales  that  satisfies  the  head  office  and  to 
show  a  maximum  profit  on  his  operations. 

"Where  a  procedure  of  this  type  is  followed  there  is  likely  to  be  a 
significant  difference  between  the  pricing  and  selling  policies  in  the 
domestic  and  export  markets.  The  domestic  department  must  usually 
offer  substantially  the  same  price  to  all  customers  of  a  particular  class, 
both  because  of  legal  restrictions  against  price  discrimination  and  be- 
cause of  the  difficulty  of  keeping  price  concessions  to  certain  customers 
a  secret  between  the  two  parties.  But  the  export  manager  usually  finds 
no  such  limitations  upon  his  pricing  and  selling  policies,  at  least  for 
distinct  national  markets.  He  can  vary  selling  expenses  from  market 
to  market,  depending  upon  what  he  thinks  will  produce  the  best 
results  in  each  market.  And  he  can  vary  prices  from  one  market  to 
another  from  a  point  at  which  the  price  covers  only  factory  cost, 
plus  out-of-pocket  expenses,  plus  a  small  portion  of  overhead  (or 
even  take  a  loss,  if  he  anticipates  a  future  return  from  developments) 
to  a  point  at  which  the  price  yields  a  substantial  profit  to  his  depart- 
ment. In  all  the  cases  of  this  type  it  was  found  that  export  prices 
varied  considerably  from  market  to  market.  While  the  export  de- 
partments in  most  instances  have  price  lists  showing  their  standard 
quotations,  the  departures  from  the  list  are  so  numerous  as  to  make 
the  standard  prices  virtually  meaningless. 

The  15  cases  shown  in  the  following  table  have  a  price  policy  of  this 
type.  It  is  obvious  that  the  company  must  be  able  to  judge  rather 
accurately  the  profitability  of  export  sales  in  all  these  cases,  even 
though  actual  profit  and  loss  statements  for  export  sales  are  not  pre- 
pared by  the  accounting  department. 

Are  export  sales  more  or  less  profitable  than  domestic? 
Products : 

1.  Stationery  and  school  supplies No  consistent  difference. 

2.  Phannaceutical  specialties Export  less  profitable. 

3.  Extensive  drug  line Do. 

4.  Extensive  drug  line No  consistent  difference. 

5.  Automotive  and  household  chemicals Export  more  profitable. 

6.  Industrial  lubricants  and  si)ecialties Export  less  profitable. 

7.  Photographic  equipment __.  Do. 

8.  Industrial  machinery  and  equipment Do. 

9.  Tools Do. 

10.  Linoleum  and  related  products Do. 

11.  Structural  insulating  and  wallboard Do. 

12.  Lime,  plaster,  and  related  building  materials.,.  Do. 

13.  Reinforced  building  paper Do. 

14.  Electrical  machinery  and  equipment Do. 

15.  Carbon  products Do. 


^4  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Example  27. — This  company  manufactures  a  high-priced  line  o'l 
stationery  products  and  school  supplies.  The  domestic  sales  depart- 
ment deals  with  jobbers,  wholesalers,  chain  stores,  commercial  and 
contact  agents,  retailers,  and  school-supply  houses.  It  issues  only  one 
price  list  which  shows  various  prices  for  each  commodity  according 
to  the  quantity  purchased.  No  special  discounts  are  given  to  any 
class  of  trade. 

The  export  department  also  issues  a  price  catalog  which  shows  con- 
siderable variation  both  above  and  below  the  domestic  prices,  item 
by  item.  But  as  most  transactions  in  export  are  made  at  some  dis- 
count from  the  prices  shown  in  the  catalog,  a  comparison  of  the 
catalog  prices  with  domestic  prices  would  not  be  very  useful.  In 
actual  practice,  the  export  sales  manager  attempts  to  set  a  price  for 
each  product  and  in  each  market  to  meet  local  competitive  conditions. 
The  net  result  is  that  each  product  is  sold  at  many  prices,  in  some 
cases  above  the  domestic  price,  but  in  many  more,  below  the  domestic 
price  for  a  comparably  sized  order. 

The  export  manager  has  a  minimum  price  below  which  he  knows 
be  cannot  go  without  causing  an  actual  loss  to  his  department.  But 
above  that  minimum  he  simply  tries  to  get  the  best  price  that  local 
market  conditions  will  allow,  taking  into  consideration  the  volume  of 
sales  that  can  be  made  at  whatever  price  he  chooses.  As  the  company 
manufactures  a  good  many  commodities  and  as  each  product  is  sold 
at  many  prices  in  various  export  markets,  some  higher,  some  the 
same,  and  some  lower  than  domestic  prices,  it  is  hardly  possible  to 
arrive  at  an  average  export  price  with  which  to  compare  the  domestic 
price  schedule.  However,  the  range  of  prices  in  exports  in  compari- 
son with  domestic  prices  is  well  illustrated  by  the  prices  of  two  of 
the  company's  more  important  products. 


Doineslic  price  per  gross... 

Argentina  (f.  a.  s.  New  York)... 

Cuba  (f.  a.  s.  New  York) 

Colombia  (f.  a.  s.  New  York). ... 
Puerto  Rico  (f.  a  s.  New  York). 
Philippines  (f.  a.  s.  New  York).. 
Mexico  (f.  a.  s.  New  York) 


Product  A 

Product  B 

$8. 00 

$18 

9.00 

27 

7.50 

21 

7.20 

24 

7.20 

18 

7.20 

21 

6.75 

18 

Prices  to  other  countries  lie  between  the  extremes  shoAvn  in  the  table. 

It  is  on  relatively  few  products  that  the  export  department  can  set 
prices  higher  than  the  domestic  price.  Export  prices  are  either  about 
the  same  or,  more  often,  lower  than  domestic  prices.  (This,  of  course, 
refers  to  invoice  prices.) 

The  company  has  separate  profit  statements  prepared  for  its  export 
and  domestic  sales.  Despite  the  fact  that  export  prices  are  1o\a  er  than 
the  domestic  prices  in  more  cases  than  they  are  higher,  the  company 
has  found  very  little  difference  between  the  profitability  of  domestic 
and  export  business.  There  is,  of  course,  some  variation  from  year 
to  year.  In  the  management's  opinion,  the  difference  in  the  rates  of 
return  from  one  year  to  another  is  more  dependent  upojn  general 
business  conditions  here  or  abroad  than  it  is  upon  whatever  price 
differences  may  exist. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


55 


Exomiple  28. — This  company  manufactures  a  few  pharmaceutical 
specialties.  Domestic  sales  are  made  to  wholesale  drug  houses  and 
retailers  large  enough  to  buy  in  wholesale  quantities.  All  sales  efforts, 
however,  are  directed  toward  the  medical  profession  itself,  as  the  prod- 
ucts are  usually  bought  by  the  consumer  only  upon  the  recommenda- 
tion of  his  physician. 

The  export  department  is  charged  by  the  laboratory  at  cost  of  pro- 
duction for  the  orders  placed  with  it,  in  the  same  way  as  the  domestic 
sales  department  is  charged.  In  the  case  of  a  few  products  the  labora- 
tory costs  for  export  are  not  the  same  as  domestic  costs,  as  special 
containers  or  other  differences  are  required.  On  several  products, 
also,  the  containers  have  directions  to  the  user  in  the  language  of  the 
country  of  destination,  and  when  the  volume  of  sales  to  that  particular 
language  group  is  small  the  cost  of  manufacture  is  increased. 

The  export  manager  states  that  in  pricing  his  product  he  tries  to 
arrive  at  an  f .  a.  s.  price  for  each  country  which  will  allow  the  product 
to  be  sold  in  the  country  of  destination  at  a  retail  price  approximately 
equal  to  similar  competing  products.  He  does  not  like  his  product  to 
be  the  highest  priced  of  its  kind  on  the  druggist's  shelf,  nor  does  he 
feel  that  it  should  be  among  the  lowest-priced  products.  The  point  is 
that  in  trying  to  arrive  at  a  retail  price  in  the  country  of  destination 
he  must  take  full  account  of  what  the  landed  cost  of  the  product  will 
be  in  that  country  in  arriving  at  his  price  in  dollars  f.  a.  s.  New  York. 
The  result  is  that  each  of  the  products  of  this  company  is  sold  in  export 
at  a  rather  wide  variety  of  prices.  The  export  manager  states  that  if 
he  does  not  happen  to  be  acquainted  with  local  competitive  conditions 
in  a  particular  market  he  is  apt  to  use  the  domestic  price  until  he  finds 
that  some  other  price  might  be  more  profitable. 

In  comparison  with  the  domestic  prices,  the  variations  in  export 
prices  are  all  downward;  that  is,  no  export  sales  are  being  made  at 
prices  higher  than  the  domestic  price,  although  there  is  some  volume 
of  exports  being  made  at  identical  prices.  The  export  manager  could 
not  even  roughly  estimate  how  much  lower  the  average  export  price 
was  than  the  domestic  price  for  any  product.  An  indication  of  the 
range  of  export  prices  can  be  obtained  from  the  following  example  of 
one  of  the  company's  major  products.  The  product  sells  in  the  do- 
mestic market  at  $8.33  per  dozen,  delivered.  At  the  present  time  this 
product  is  being  exported  to  24  foreign  markets  at  the  following  net 
prices,  f .  a.  s.  New  York : 


19  countries $8.  35 

1  country 7.  75 

1  country 6.  95 


1    country $6.  56 

1  country 5.30 

1  country 5.00 


It  SO  happens  that  in  this  case  the  laboratory  costs  are  the  same  for 
export  as  for  domestic  sales. 

While  the  export  department  consistently  shows  a  profit  after  pay- 
ing laboratory  costs,  general  overhead,  and  expenses  of  the  export 
department,  this  net  profit  on  sales  is  consistently  lower  than  that  of 
the  domestic  sales  department.  The  reasons  for  this  are  as  follows: 
(1)  The  average  domestic  prices  are  higher  than  the  average  export 
prices;  (2)  the  laboratory  costs  of  manufacturing  for  domestic  are 
lower;  (3)  both  sales  departments  have  approximately  the  same  pro- 
portionate expenses  in  soliciting  the  profession,  but  the  export  depart- 
ment must  pay  commissions  to  local  agents  while  the  domestic  depart- 


55  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

rnent  has  no  comparable  sales  expense;  (4)  the  profit  of  the  export 
department  is  continually  reduced  by  exchange  losses  where  sales  are 
being  made  in  local  currency.  It  has  largely  discontinued  the  practice 
of  pricing  in  terms  of  local  currency,  after  experiencing  substantial 
exchange  losses  during  the  past  decade. . 

Example  £9. — This  company  manufactures  an  extensive  line  of 
pharmaceutical  products,  including  biological  products,  home  neces- 
sities, vitamin  products,  pharmaceuticals,  professional  pharmaceutical 
specialties, 'and  chemicals  for  the  drug  trade.  The  export  department 
has  complete  autonomy  over  export  prices  and  tries  to  set  an  f .  a.  s. 
export  price  for  each  foreign  market  so  that  the  local  merchants  will 
be  able  to  sell  the  product  at  approximately  the  same  price  as  compet- 
ing products  in  that  market.  Where  there  is  no  need  for  a  special 
export  price  or  where  the  export  manager  is  not  sufficiently  acquainted 
with  local  conditions  to  set  a  special  price,  the  domestic  price  for  the 
product  is  used.  A  large  share  of  the  export  sales  are  made  at  prices 
identical  with  domestic. 

A  few  products  are  sold  in  some  foreign  markets  as  much  as  10 
percent  higher  than  the  domestic  price,  and  many  more  are  sold  at 
lower  than  domestic  prices  with  the  diflFerential  as  high  as  25  percent. 

The  costs  of  doing  business  differ  widely  from  market  to  market 
and  on  the  whole  differ  considerably  from  domestic  distribution  costs. 
The  export  department  has  profit  statements  prepared  separately  for 
every  foreign  country  to  which  it  exports,  precisely  the  same  as  the 
domestic  department  has  separate  statements  prepared  for  its  various 
branches  throughout  the  country.  Profitability  of  export  sales  varies 
from  country  to  country,  but  on  the  whole,  no  more  so  than  the 
profits  earned  by  the  various  domestic  sales  branches.  On  the  average, 
the  export  business  is  just  as  profitable  as  domestic. 

Example  SO. — The  following  case  is  particularly  interesting,  as  it 
illustrates  the  variety  of  selling  procedures  that  has  been  virtually 
forced  upon  many  manufacturers  because  of  the  development  of 
diverse  types  of  retail  distribution  of  consumers'  goods.  The  com- 
pany manufactures  over  a  hundred  products  which  can  best  be  classi- 
fied as  automotive  chemicals  and  household  specialties. 

Ignoring  the  complications  of  corporate  structure  which  have  no 
significant  influence  upon  the  conduct  of  the  business,  the  selling 
procedure  of  the  company  may  be  described  as  follows :  In  order  to 
service  the  domestic  market,  the  organization  has  several  selling 
departments,  each  of  which  caters  to  an  individual  type  of  customer, 
such  as  5-and-lO-cent  stores,  automotive  chain  stores,  large  depart- 
ment stores,  private-brand  wholesalers,  and  independent  jobbers  and 
dealers.  The  company's  own  branded  line  of  products  which  is 
nationally  advertised  and  its  first-quality  merchandise  are  sold  only 
to  independent  jobbers  and  dealers.  The  other  types  of  trade  buy 
unadvertised  brands  or  nonbranded  products  on  a  strictly  price  basis. 
In  some  cases,  the  actual  contents  of  a  container  in  the  nondescript 
brand  may  be  exactly  the  same  as  a  product  sold  under  the  com- 
pany's own  brand.  In  other  cases,  the  size  of  the  container  may  be 
varied;  for  example,  to  allow  the  product  to  be  sold  at  a  profit  in 
5-and-lO-cent  stores.  In  still  other  cases  the  product  itself  may  be 
cheapened  in  order  to  get  it  down  to  a  price  class  that  meets  the 
customer's  needs.    The  important  factor,  however,  which  makes  all 


OONCENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER  57 

other  prices  lower  than  those  of  the  branded  line  is  the  small  propor- 
tion of  selling  costs  when  advertising  is  eliminated  and  quantity  sales 
are  made. 

Each  of  these  sales  departments  is  billed  by  the  factory  at  factory- 
cost  whether  these  costs  are  the  same,  higher,  or  lower  than  the  cost 
of  similar  products  in  the  company's  branded  line.  Each  of  the.  sales 
departments  is  also  charged  with  the  direct  expenses  of  its  depart- 
ment plus  its  share  of  the  general  administrative  overhead,  and  is 
expected  to  earn  a  profit  over  these  costs. 

The  export  department  handles  only  the  company's  branded  line 
of  products.  It  is  charged  by  the  factory  exactly  the  same  as  the 
corresponding  domestic  sales  department  handling  the  same  line  of 
products,  and  it  is  expected  to  cover  its  departmental  expenses,  its 
share  of  general  administrative  overhead,  and  to  show  a  profit  above 
these  costs. 

The  selling  expenses  of  the  domestic  department  servicing  inde- 
pendent jobbers  and  dealers  are  vastly  greater  than  those  of  the 
export  department.  It  advertises  on  a  national  scale.  It  has  a  host 
of  salesmen  covering  the  country  from  one  end  to  the  other.  The 
export  department,  on  the  other  hand,  handles  the  bulk  of  its  busi- 
ness by  mail  except  for  occasional  trips  abroad  by  the  export  mana- 
ger. The  export  department  has  virtually  no  advertising  expenses. 
Thus,  while  the  export  department  handles  exactly  the  same  products 
as  the  corresponding  domestic  department,  its  entire  selling  pro- 
cedure is  different. 

Other  than  the  product  itself,  the  only  competitive  weapon  which 
the  export  manager  employs  to  help  him  increase  the  volume  of  his 
sales  is  price.  He  may  have  a  different  price  for  almost  each  of  the 
150  markets  to  which  he  sells.  He  varies  the  price  according  to  the 
type  of  representation  he  has  in  the  foreign  market;  that  is,  jobbers, 
dealers,  manufacturers'  agent,  or  exclusive  distributors.  He  varies 
it  also  according  to  local  competitive  conditions  and  to  what  the 
retail  price  in  the  local  market  must  be  after  landed  cost  and  the 
dealer's  margin  have  been  added  to  the  f,  a.  s,  price.  The  conse- 
quence is  that  the  range  of  prices  at  which  export  sales  are  consum- 
mated is  very  wide.  The  lowest  price  is  considerably  less  than  the 
domestic  price  even  allowing  for  a  much  higher  proportion  of  selling 
cost  in  the  domestic  market,  while  the  highest  price  in  export  is 
considerably  above  tlie  domestic  price  if  allowance  was  made  for  the 
difference  in  sales  expenses.  As  an  example  of  the  range  in  export 
nrices  and  the  comparison  with  the  domestic  price  for  an  identical 
product,  the  following  figures  are  representative. 

Domestic  price  per  dozen $3.  51 

Export  prices: 

Colombia,  Gibraltar,  New  Guinea,  etc 3.  24 

Japan 2.  55 

Syria 2.50 

Union  of  South  Africa 2.  40 

Cuba,  Uruguay 2.  25 

New  Zealand 2. 15 

India ; 2.02 

Argentina 2.  00 

England 1.96 

Belgium 1.76 

Australia : 1.75 

France 1.50 


5g  OONOENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER 

These  prices  are  f .  a.  s.  New  York,  in  wholesale  quantities.  Ketail 
prices  abroad,  after  payment  of  ocean  freight  and  duties  are  invar- 
iably higher  than  the  domestic  retail  price.  For  example,  on  the 
above  product,  which  retails  in  the  American  market  at  $0.60;  the 
price  in  England  at  the  current  rate  of  exchange  is  $1.12;  Australia, 
$0.85;  France,  $0.86;  Union  of  South  Africa,  $0.74;  the  Argentine, 
$0,621/2. 

The  export  manager  explained  that  his  rule-of-thumb  method  of 
pricing  is  to  double  the  price  at  which  the  product  is  charged  to  him 
by  the  factory.  He  knows  from  experience  that  if  on  the  average  he 
gets  double  the  factory  cost  for  each  product,  at  the  end  of  the  year 
his  department  will  show  a  profit.  For  example,  the  factory  costs 
for  the  above  product  are  $1.02,  so  that  even  the  price  to  France  of 
$1.50  covers  the  factory  cost,  the  out-of-pocket  expenses  of  the  export 
department,  and  part  of  the  administrative  overhead  with  which  the 
department  is  charged. 

As  has  been  indicated  above,  the  operating  expenses  of  the  export 
department  are  considerably  lower  than  the  operating  expenses  of 
the  domestic  department  handling  the  company's  branded  line  of 
products.  The  manager  of  the  domestic  department  states  that  his 
department's  expenses,  that  is,  the  selling  expenses,  average  approxi- 
mately 50  percent  of  receipts  from  sales,  while  the  export  manager 
states  that  his  departmental  expenses  vary  between  20  and  35  percent 
of  sales  per  month,  depending  upon  the  profitability  of  the  items  ex- 
ported and  the  market  to  w  dch  the  bulk  of  the  shipments  happen 
to  go.  There  is  no  way  of  comparing  the  overall  experience  of  these 
two  departments  except  by  the  profitability  of  their  operations.  This 
comparison  is  a  very  simple  one  because  of  all  the  departments  in  this 
organization,  the  only  one  which  has  consistently  lost  money  in  recent 
years  is  the  domestic  sales  department  which  handles  the  branded 
line.  The  export  department  has  continuously  shown  a  substantial 
profit,  as  have  the  other  domestic  sales  departments.  But  the  domes- 
tic sales  department  which  services  independent  jobbers  and  dealers 
has  for  years  been  faced  with  higher  and  higher  selling  costs  as  its 
volume  of  sales  have  tended  to  decrease.  In  fact,  the  company  was 
forced  to  sell  to  the  newer  merchandising  outlets  (chain  stores,  etc.) 
because  its  sales  to  independent  dealers  were  dwindling  and  it  thus 
had  no  outlet,  or  not  sufRcife:it  outlet,  for  its  manufacturing  capacity. 

Type  11. 

All  foreign  sales  made  hy  company  hranches;  concessions  in  some 
murkets. — There  is  a  similar  type  of  export  price  procedure  which, 
while  followed  by  several  cases  in  the  sample  for  part  of  their  export 
business,  was  employed  exclusively  by  only  one  case.  This  method 
of  pricing  is  one  which  can  be  used  only  by  firms  with  foreign  selling 
branches.  The  foreign  branches  are  invoiced  at  factory  costs  and  they 
fix  their  prices  independently  of  domestic  prices.  The  invoice  prices 
are  only  nominal,  representing  intercompany  bookkeeping  entries, 
and  they  do  not  include  any  profit  on  liie  transaction.  The  foreign 
branch  must  calculate  its  landed  cost,  its  local  distribution  costs,  and 
attempt  to  get  prices  and  volume  large  enough  to  yield  a  profit. 

This  system  is  being  used  by  several  cases  in  the  sample,  for  part 
of  their  exports,  usually  by  companies  with  branch  factories  abroad. 
Goods  are  shipped  in  a  semimanufactured  condition  and  finished 


OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  59 

abroad.  Either  because  a  large  proportion  of  the  final  costs  are  con- 
tracted abroad  or  because  it  otherwise  facilitates  the  conduct  of  the 
business,  the  foreign  branch  is  billed  at  factory  costs  and  profits  are 
reported  as  earned  by  the  branch.  But  in  these  cases  most  of  the  ex- 
ports are  to  independent  importers  and  the  price  comparison  pre- 
sented in  the  study  made  was  between  those  export  sales  and  domestic 
sales.     Branch  factory  transfers  could  thus  be  ignored. 

In  one  case,  however,  all  export  sales  are  made  to  foreign  branches — 
the  company  and  its  foreign  affiliates  handle  all  business.  There  is 
no  intermediary  between  it  and  the  consumer,  either  in  domestic  or 
foreign  markets. 

The  approximate  measure  of  price  differences  in  such  a  case  is  the 
net  per  unit  profit  market  by  market.  Since  each  factory  branch  is 
billed  at  factory  costs  to  which  it  must  add  all  its  distribution  costs, 
the  net  return  per  unit  of  sales  measures  the  difference  in  price  above 
differences  in  costs. 

In  this  case  the  net  return  on  sales  in  several  foreign  markets  is  con- 
siderably lower  than  the  net  return  earned  by  any  sales  branch  in  the 
domestic  market.  Not  only  are  prices  adjusted  to  the  lower  purchas- 
ing power  prevailing  in  those  foreign  markets  but  a  cheaper  product, 
not  sold  in  the  domestic  market,  is  produced  for  them  upon  which  a 
relatively  smaller  mark-up  is  included  in  the  price. 

Type  12. 

All  foreign  sales  rtiade  at  less  than  average  costs. — All  the  cases  of 
group  III  which  have  been  discussed  up  to  this  point  generally  operate 
their  export  departments  at  a  profit  with  all  costs  considered.  Al- 
though the  export  prices  on  some  products  or  some  transactions  are 
often  less  than  long  run  or  full  costs  of  production — i.  e.,  the  export 
price  does  not  cover  full  overhead  or  even  factory  costs — the  prices 
on  export  business  as  a  whole  are  high  enough  to  cover  all  costs  and 
yield  a  profit.  The  rate  of  profit  on  exports  is  as  has  been  pointed 
out,  often  less  than  the  rate  of  profit  on  domestic  business  but,  except 
during  periods  of  depressed  business  conditions,  the  export  depart- 
ment is  profitable. 

The  next  six  cases  have  been  grouped  together  because  in  all  of  them 
virtually  all  export  sales  are  consummated  at  prices  which  do  not 
cover  full  or  average  costs.  It  is,  perhaps,  straining  a  point  to  speak 
of  this  as  an  export-price  policy.  Nevertheless,  these  cases  are  similar 
in  the  results  achieved  by  their  export  departments.  In  the  products 
handled  by  these  firms  export  sales  can  be  obtained  only  at  prices 
which  do  not  cover  full  factory  and  administrative  overhead.  It 
might  be  said  that  the  price  policy  is  to  accept  export  business  at  any 
price  above  out-of-pocket  costs  or  even  less  on  the  transaction.  An  ex- 
port department  which  cannot  earn  a  profit  after  being  charged  with 
its  full  costs  is,  nevertheless,  operated  because  its  sales  reduce  over- 
head, cut  factory  costs,  or  in  some  other  way  assist  in  the  conduct  of 
the  business.  However,  occasional  sales  in  all  the  cases  of  group  III 
are  probably  made  at  prices  equally  low.  But  in  the  six  cases  consid- 
ered here  there  simply  is  not  any  other  export  business  at  offsetting 
higher  prices. 

It  is  quite  probable  that  in  some  of  these  cases  a  small  volume  of 
export  sales  would  be  obtained  even  if  the  firm  refused  to  sell  at  less 
than  domestic  prices  but  the  volume  would  be  too  small  to  maintain 


gQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

an  export  organization  or  even  an  export  manager  equipped  to  handle 
the  business.  The  low  export  j)rices  are  quoted,  therefore,  in  order 
to  get  a  volume  of  business  sufficiently  large  to  enable  the  company  to 
maintain  a  staff  equipped  to  handle  export  orders.  In  other  of  these 
eases,  however,  no  export  sales  could  be  secured  at  domestic  prices. 
The  products  of  these  six  firms  are : 

1.  Cotton  yarns. 

2.  Household  cotton  textile  products. 

3.  Plumbing  fixtures  and  related  products. 

4.  Specialized  chemical  products. 

5.  Glass  products. 

6.  Glass  products. 

A  few  examples  will  reveal  that  the  circumstances  in  these  cases 
are  not  identical  except  for  the  fact  that  export  prices  are  substan- 
tially below  domestic  price.  There  is  a  common  element  of  policy 
in  the  fact  that  these  firms  engage  in  exporting  at  ail  in  the  fact 
of  quite  unfavorable  foreign  market  conditions.  Many  other  firms 
including  some  of  those  in  our  sample  would  simply  forego  export- 
ing under  such  conditions. 

Example  31. — This  firm  produces  certain  household  textile  prod- 
ucts of  which  turkish  and  hand  towels  and  bed  linens  are  the  im- 
portant items.  The  domestic  market  is  serviced  by  various  sales 
departments,  each  selling  to  a  distinct  type  of  trade — e.  g.,  independ- 
ent retailers,  wholesalers,  department  stores,  chain  stores,  institu- 
tions, etc.  Products  are  manufactured  specially  for  each  type  of 
trade  according  to  the  price  class  required  and  each  line  of  products 
is  sold  only  to  the  type  of  trade  for  which  it  was  designed.  The 
salas  departments  usually  have  a  quantity  scale  of  prices  and  dis- 
cretionary prices  which  can  be  used  by  the  salesmen  under  special 
circumstances. 

The  export  department  does  not  have  a  special  line  of  products 
but  it  can  sell  any  of  the  products  of  the  domestic  sales  department 
without  regard  to  the  type  of  customers.  It  can,  furthermore,  sell 
in  small  quantities  at  the  domestic  quantity  and  discretionary  prices. 
There  are  very  few  large  orders  in  its  export  business  and  the  small 
orders  could  not  be  obtained  at  the  domestic  prices  for  comparably 
sized  orders.  In  addition  the  company  must  pay  foreign  agents 
commission  of  5  percent,  which  it  considers  a  net  addition  to  costs 
as  domestic  and  other  export  distribution  expenses  are  otherwise  about 
equal.  Even  with  these  price  concessions  there  is  little  foreign  demand 
for  its  products.  The  export  business  is  in  the  specialty  goods  rather 
than  the  staple  products  of  the  company. 

The  management  has  never  been  enthusiastic  about  export  business 
because  foreign  prices  are  so  much  lower  than  those  prevailing  in  the 
American  market. 

Example  32. — The  product  in  this  case  is  a  specialized  chemical 
commodity.  European  competition  quotes  approximately  40  percent 
under  United  States  prices,  delivered  in  Latin  American  markets. 
This  firm  takes  business  at  approximately  20  percent  less  than  its 
domestic  prices.  At  such  prices  it  gets  a  significant  volume  in  only 
one  market,  Cuba,  where  American  products  receive  preferential 
tariff  treatment.  While  the  firm  gets  occasional  orders  from  other 
markets  these  are  small  in  total  and  of  an  accommodation  character 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  QJ 

where  fast  delivery  or  some  other  factor  compensates  the  buyer  for 
the  higher  than  European  price.  There  is  no  significant  export  market 
for  this  product. 

Example  33. — This  company  manufactures  plumbing  fixtures  and 
related  products.  In  the  domestic  market  it  distributes  through  its 
own  branches  direct  to  the  trade  or  through  independent  wholesalers. 
The  company's  branches  and  independent  wholesalers  are  charged  at 
the  same  prices. 

A  large  part  of  the  export  business  is  done  at  the  domestic  wholesale 
prices  but  in  order  to  do  this  the  company  must  give  the  export  de- 
partment a  10  percent  discount  from  domestic  wholesale  prices.  Of 
this  10  percent,  5  percent  is  required  for  commission  to  the  foreign 
agent  and  5  percent  for  the  expenses  of  the  expor*-  department.  The 
net  to  the  company  is,  therefore,  approximately  10  percent  less  on  ex- 
port than  on  domestic  business. 

Moreover,  on  occasion,  an  additional  10  percent  discount  is  given 
in  export  if  it  is  necessary  to  get  volume  business. 

Type  13. 

Export  agents  and  commission  houses. — The  remaining  three  cases 
are  export  trading  companies  which  do  not  manufacture  and  do  not 
have  any  domestic  business.  Most  of  their  business  is  as  commission 
representatives  of  the  United  States  manufacturers  but  two  of  them 
buy  and  sell  on  their  own  account.  They  were  included  in  the  sample 
in  an  effort  to  determine  the  export  pricing  policies  of  American  manu- 
facturers who  export  through  commission  agents.  The  information 
presented  below  came  from  the  export  commission  house  and  not  from 
the  manufacturers  themselves.  In  all  three  of  these  cases  a  consid- 
erable part  of  the  exports  are  at  lower  than  domestic  prices. 

Exam^ple  SJf. — This  company  is  an  export  commission  house  which  is 
handling  the  following  products  in  export  markets  for  American 
manufacturers : 

Men's  shoes.  Cosmetics. 

Underwear,  men's  and  women's.  Textile  finishes. 

Men's  shirts.  Dyeing  machinery. 

Pajamas,  men's  and  women's.  Industrial  products  for  hosiery  and 

Girdles.  girdle  manufacturers. 

Shoes,  underwear,  shirts,  pajamas,  and  girdles  are  sold  by  the  ex- 
porter for  approximately  the  same  prices  (on  an  f.  o,  b,  basis)  as  they 
are  sold  b}^  the  domestic  manufacturers.  The  exporter  works  on  a 
commission  that  is  usual  for  this  type  of  business.  There  could  not  be 
much  difference,  if  any,  between  selling  costs  in  the  domestic  market 
and  the  exporter's  commission,  so  the  net  return  to  the  manufacturer 
in  each  case  is  probably  about  the  same  on  export  as  on  domestic  sales. 

Export  prices  on  the  other  products  are  all  lower  than  domestic 
prices ;  10  to  15  percent  lower  on  cosmetics,  20  percent  lower  on  textile 
finishes  and  dyeing  machinery,  and  about  10  percent  lower  on  indus- 
trial products.  In  these  cases  the  producing  mills  are  inclined  to  look 
upon  exports  as  windfall  business  to  take  up  some  of  their  excess 
capacity.  Obviously  they  consider  it  more  profitable  to  take  it  at  the 
price  than  to  forego  the  business  altogether.  Bat  (according  to  the 
export  agent)  they  would  be  out  of  business  if  domestic  prices  were  as 
low  as  export. 


Ao  OONGETiTIlATIOr^  OF  EOOnOMIC  power 

Example  35. — This  company  deals  in  all  types  of  cotton  staples  and 
yarns.  It  is  the  export  selling  agent  for  many  domestic  mills  and  also 
buys  and  sells  on  its  own  account. 

For  products  of  this  type  domestic  prices  are  very  competitive  and 
the  margin  of  profit  rather  small.  There  are  many  producers  of  each 
product  and  price  quotations  are  easily  available  and  well  known. 

On  the  general  run  of  exjjort  business  the  export  agent  merely  quotes 
the  market  price  and  receives  its  selling  commission  from  the  mill. 
Its  agents  abroad  are  furnished  with  price  quotations  but  they  con- 
tinually cable  offers  at  lower  prices.  Such  offers  are  submitted  to  a 
mill  manufacturing  the  particular  product  and  it  either  accepts,  re- 
jects, or  makes  a  counter  offer.  The  agent  himself  cannot  quote  under 
the  market  price.  The  price  concessions  that  the  mills  may  accept  are 
always  small — less  than  5  percent. 

The  view  taken  by  the  mills  is  much  different.  Some  are  more  will- 
ing to  make  price  concessions  than  others,  and  in  any  case  the  willing- 
ness to  make  a  concession  is  quite  dependent  upon  how  good  domestic 
business  is. 

The  commission  paid  the  exporter  is  larger  than  usual  domestic  sell- 
ing costs  on  this  type  of  staple  merchandise.  The  exporter  must  cover 
the  costs  of  export  packing,  foreign  agents'  commissions,  cables,  cart- 
age in  New  York,  and  his  general  overhead  and  profit.  Therefore,  the 
net  return  to  the  mills  must  be  less  on  export  business  in  almost  all 
instances  even  when  sales  are  made  at  the  market  price. 


CHAPTER  VI 

THE  ECONOMIC  FACTORS  DETERMINING  EXPORT 
PRICE  POLICY 

In  this  chapter  an  effort  will  be  made  to  explain  the  reasons  for  the 
diverse  price  policies  disclosed  in  chapter  V.  To  be  sufficiently  com- 
prehensive, this  explanation  must  embrace  the  reasons  of  management 
for  its  price  behavior  and  also  the  economic  or  objective  factors  which 
limit  management  in  its  choice  of  price  policy.  Explaining  price  be- 
havior is  a  precarious  task,  so  that  the  discussion  to  follow  must  be 
considered  tentative  and  exploratory  rather  than  definitive. 

EXPORT  PRICES  HIGHER  THAN  DOMESTIO  PRICES 

When  an  individual  or  a  group  of  individuals  orp^anize  a  business 
enterprise  there  is  a  presumption  that  all  efforts  will  be  directed  to 
making  profits  as  large  as  possible  within  the  limitations  of  legal  re- 
strictions and  current  business  mores.  It  is  to  be  expected  that  any 
firm  will  try  to  get  that  price  for  its  product  which  will  yield  the 
greatest  net  return  on  its  total  operations.  The  impediments  to  a  rela- 
tively high  price  are  due,  in  general,  to  the  prices  of  competing  or 
substitute  products,  and/or  the  reduced  volume  of  sales  that  i-esults 
as  the  price  is  increased,  and/or  the  variation  in  costs  per  unit  of 
product  as  the  output  is  reduced.  If,  in  view  of  these  conditions,  a 
higher  price  will  result  in  larger  profits,  there  is  a  presumption  that 
any  firm  will  charge  the  higher  price.  No  particular  rationalization, 
therefore,  is  required  to  explain  the  willingness  of  the  firms  in  group  I 
to  charge  higher  prices  on  export  shipments  than  in  the  domestic 
market.  With  their  knowledge  of  demand  and  cost  conditions,  they 
presumably  are  convinced  that  the  higher  export  prices  -make  their 
business  more  profitable  than  a  price  equal  to,  or  lower  than,  the 
domestic  price.  What  does  require  explaiiation,  however,  is  how  they 
are  able  to  get  the  higher  price.  What  peculiar  circumstances  give 
these  firms  the  power  to  exact  a  higher  export  price  and  what  prevents 
an  equally  high  price  in  the  domestic  market  ? 

With  regard  to  the  cases  of  type  I  the  answer  to  this  question  is 
quite  simple.  The  products  in  both  these  cases  are  derived  from  a 
raw  material  of  which  the  major  economically  available  supply  is  in 
the  United  States.  Export  prices  in  these  cases  are  admittedly  mo- 
nopoly prices.  This  export  monopoly  rests  upon  two  factors :  (1)  The 
United  States  producers  collectively  control  a  dominant  share  of 
world  output  and  (2)  they  are  effectively  organized  to  control  export 
prices — in  these  cases  legally  under  the  provisions  of  the  Webb- 
Pomerene  Act.  Both  of  these  factors  are  necessary  for  the  mainte- 
nance of  the  higher  export  price.  There  must  be  control  of  output 
over  the  relevant  price  range.    It  is  obvious  that  the  supply  abroad 

63 


QA  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER. 

must  be  relatively  inelastic;  that  is,  foreign  production  must  not  in- 
crease much  when  the  price  goes  up,  or  the  American  producers  will 
lose  their  foreign  markets  as  they  raise  the  price.  And  while  the 
control  of  supply  would  be  ineffective  without  the  organization  to 
exercise  that  control,  the  organization  in  itself  cannot  create  that 
control.  In  all  there  are  six  Webb-Pomerene  export  corporations  in 
our  sample  and  only  two  fall  in  group  I.  Two  of  the  others  are  in 
group  II  and  two  in  group  III. 

As  the  producers  in  these  industries  do  not  have  the  legal  right  to 
organize  and  fix  prices  in  the  domestic  market  the  presumption  is 
that  the  lower  prices  in  the  domestic  market  are  due  to  the  degree  of 
competition.  While  this  does  not  mean  that  competition  is  abso- 
lutely unfettered  among  the  producers  in  the  domestic  market  the 
latter  obviously  does  not  have  the  same  legal  freedom  to  fix  monopo- 
listic prices  as  in  export  markets.  Possibly  there  is  no  agreement  as 
to  prices  in  the  domestic  market ;  possibly  the  producers  are  deterred 
from  fixing  a  higher  domestic  price  because  an  antitrust  action  might 
be  instituted;  or  possibly  the  -deterrent  is  the  likelihood  that  large 
domestic  consumers  would  force  their  way  into  the  industry.  One 
can  hardly  expect  to  get  an  adequate  and  precise  answer  to  this 
question  from  the  industry  itself. 

It  is  interesting  to  inquire  how  it  is  that  the  foreign  customer  can- 
not buy  at  the  domestic  price  simply  by  concealing  his  identity  or  by 
using  a  third  party  in  the  United  States  as  an  agent.  In  example  1, 
where  the  differential  between  export  and  domestic  price  was  20  per- 
cent, there  would  seem  to  be  a  pecuniary  inducement  large  enough  to 
lead  to  "bootlegging"  of  the  product  out  of  the  United  States.  The 
management  in  this  case  states  that  the  problem  has  never  arisen  but 
that  foreign  customer^  could  not  buy  at  domestic  prices  for  two  rea- 
sons. (1)  The  producers  are  well  acquainted  with  the  trade  and  know 
who  in  the  domestic  market  is  buying  for  his  own  use.  If  an  order 
came  in  from  an  unknown  person  and  the  destination  of  the  shipment 
was  uncertain,  they  simply  would  not  sell  to  him  at  the  domestic  price. 
(2)  On  the  other  hand,  the  customers  who  are  buying  at  the  domestic 
price  would  have  little  margin  to  cut  the  export  price  after  paying 
freight  costs  and  repacking  for  export  shipment.  Unless  they  directed 
shipment  to  the  nearest  port  of  export  they  could  hardly  sell  under  the 
export  price  of  the  company,  and  they  could  not  request  delivery  at 
the  nearest  port  of  export  without  revealing  their  intention  to  the 
company. 

While  the  cases  in  type  2  do  not  have  the  monopoly  element  in  ex- 
port markets  that  the  cases  of  type  1  have,  the  ba^ic  explanation  for 
the  higher  export  prices  is  still  that  these  firms  are  faced  with  a 
higher  degree  of  competition  in  the  domestic  market  than  in  their 
export  markets.  The  products  in  all  three  cases  of  type  2  are  more 
or  less  standardized  commodities  3old  to  industrial  consumere  for 
whom  a  brand  name  is  of  little  significant.  Prices  for  export  are 
quoted  c.  i.  f .  and  either  there  are  no  f .  o.  b.  prices  known  to  the  export 
customer  or  he  is  unable  to  arrange  for  shipment  himself. 

Consider  the  facts  given  in  example  3.  The  company  sells  in  export 
at  c.  i.  f.  prices  for  which  mill  net3  vary  as  much  as  16  percent,  and  its 
mill  net  on  export  sales  is  never  less  than  its  net  realization  on  domestic 
sales.    Why  is  this  rather  wide  variation  in  export  prices  possible? 


CONCENTRATION  OF  E<X>NOMIC  POWER  g5 

The  customer,  of  course,  13  interested  in  getting  the  product  at  a  landed 
cost  which  will  enable  him  to  use  it  profitably  or  more  profitably 
than  using  some  other  material.  His  landed  cost  is  equal  to  the  c.  i.  f . 
price  plus  the  import  duty.  A  very  high  duty  will  make  sales  impos- 
sible, and  it  is  only  in  countries  that  have  no  local  industry  producing 
a  similar  product  and  where  the  duty  is  for  revenue  purposes  that  the 
company  can  get  any  business.  A  relatively  low  rate  of  duty  or  a 
favorable  ocean  freight  rate  or  both  will  usually  allow  the  company 
to  get  a  higher  f.  o.  b.  price.  Or  it  may  be  that  these  costs  are  merely 
lower  than  similar  costs  for  a  substitute  product.  Factors  3uch  as 
these  determine  local  market  conditions.  The  company  is  able  to  vary 
its  price  for  export  in  accordance  with  local  market  conditions  because 
the  various  local  markets  are  independent  of  each  other. 

Wliat  if  local  market  conditions  demand  a  lower  ,f .  o.  b.  price  than 
the  average  domestic  net  ( f .  o.  b. )  price  ?  The  answer  is  merely  that 
the  company,  as  a  matter  of  policy,  is  not  interested  in  export  business 
at  such  prices  and  will  not  consummate  sales  that  yield  less  than  its 
domestic  net  price.  The  company  ha^  not  been  burdened  with  any 
serious  excess  capacity,  it  has  not  been  forced  to  seek  new  markets 
for  its  output,  and  it  has,  in  fact,  been  drawn  into  the  export  business 
only  because  it  could  get  more  attractive  prices.  In  other  words,  the 
company  has  a  favorable  business  position  in  the  domestic  market 
which  permits  considerable  latitude  with  regard  to  export  price  policy. 
But  the  rationale  of  export  price  policy  from  the  standpoint  of  the 
company  does  not  explain  the  economic  conditions  which  allow  the 
company  to  maintain  that  policy.  Why  is  it,  then,  that  the  company 
can  get  a  higher  price  abroad  than  it  can  at  home  ? 

The  answer  is  tliat  there  is  less  competition  from  other  mills  in  the 
industry  for  export  business,  than  for  domestic  business.  Most  of  the 
mills  in  the  industry  make  no  attempt  to  get  export  sales,  but  they  do 
compete  on  a  price  basis  for  domestic  business.  There  are  several 
reasons  for  this  condition.  In  the  first  place,  while  it  is  easy  to  canvass 
the  domestic  consuming  trade  by  telephone  or  in  person  it  is  not  so  easy 
to  make  contacts  with  the  foreign  consumers.  It  could  be  done,  but  it 
is  expensive  and  the  volume  of  business  that  a  mill  just  entering  export 
could  get  would  hardly  pay  for  the  effort  and  expense  of  getting  it. 
Then,  too,  the  industry  knows  that  the  possible  volume  of  export  busi- 
ness is  not  great  enough  to  warrant  the  attention  of  many  mills,  so 
there  is  not  much  incentive  to  go  after  export  business.  Another  factor 
of  importance  is  that  many  mills  are  not  located  on  tidewater,  hence 
not  so  favorably  situated  to  export  their  product.  They  could  not 
accept  export  business  unless  the  price  covered  inland  freight,  and  for 
those  located  far  enough  inland  this  would  erase  the  price  differential. 
It  must  also  be  remembered  that  the  export  prices  of  the  exporting 
company  are  very  much  a  business  secret.  The  foreign  buyer,  on  the 
other  hand,  would  probably  be  faced  with  difficulties  in  getting  another 
supplier  even  if  he  knows  that  he  might  be  able  to  get  a  lower  price. 
He  does  business  Avith  the  foreign  agent  on  the  spot  and  no  other  agmts 
compete  for  his  trade.  He  cannot  without  expense  contact  other  fixuis 
and  as  he  knows  their  United  States  delivered  prices,  which  are  either 
identical  with  or  comparatively  close  to  the  domestic  prices  of  the  firm 
with  which  he  is  already  dealing,  he  probably  sees  little  incentive  to 
do  so.     For  these  reasons  competitive  forces  have  failed  to  break 


gg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

through  the  established  lines  of  trade  and  bring  export  prices  down 
to  domestic  prices.  The  companj^  that  was  in  the  export  market  first 
remains  in  an  advantageous  position.  Quite  possibly  this  condition  is 
not  a  permanent  one,  but  the  result  only  of  what  are  usually  called 
frictional  impediments  to  the  operation  of  the  competitive  process.  At 
the  present  time,  however,  the  export  business  is  a  series  of  isolated 
transactions  in  which  the  buyer  and  seller  agree  on  a  price.  The  buyer 
apparently  has  only  limited  knowledge  of  the  American  market  and 
the  seller  has  only  limited  competition.  Prices  are  not  made  in  af  airly 
well  informed  market  consisting  of  a  number  of  buyers  and  sellers,  as 
is  more  or  less  the  case  in  the  United  States. 

The  explanation  of  higher  export  prices  in  the  other  two  cases  of 
type  2  is  quite  similar ;  more  firms  are  competing  in  the  domestic  market 
than  in  the  export  market.  Coupled  with  this  is  the  fact  that  the 
exporting  firms  are  in  a  position  to  maintain  their  price  policy ;  that 
is,  they  can  refuse  export  business  that  does  not  yield  a  higher  net 
return  than  domestic  sales. 

The  economic  or  technological  factors  that  restrict  the  export  busi- 
ness to  fewer  firms  than  compete  in  the  domestic  market  differ  from 
industry  to  industry.  In  one  of  these  cases  the  risk  factor  which  has 
arisen  in  the  past  decade  of  exchange  restrictions  is  an  important  deter- 
rent while  in  the  other  case  the  complicated  character  of  exporting 
techniques  and  the  elaborate  organization  required  to  handle  exports 
prevents  the  smaller  firms  from  competing  for  this  business. 

The  greater  degree  of  competition  in  the  domestic  market  is  also  the 
explanation  of  higher  export  prices  in  the  type  3  cases.  Because  fewer 
firms  are  competing  for  the  export  market  it  has  been  possible  to  main- 
tain higher  list  prices  and  proportionately  lower  selling  costs.  The 
products  in  these  cases  are  branded  consumers'  goods  and  all  the  brands 
have  definite  consumer  appeal.  The  company  is  able  to  exact  a  slightly 
higher  price  from  the  foreign  distributor,  because  no  one  else  can 
supply  him  with  that  particular  branded  line,  of  products.  The  com- 
pany appoints  him  the  distributor  and  his  business  thereby  becomes  tied 
up  with  a  particular  brand.  The  distributor  is  hardly  in  a  position  to 
do  anything  but  accept  the  price  quoted  him  by  the  company. 

Why  are  not  more  domestic  producers  competing  in  export  mar- 
kets? Many  companies  can  produce  and  sell  for  thd  package  trade 
of  the  domestic  market  but  to  do  an  effective  job  in  export  is  a  more 
difficult  matter.  The  mere  problem  of  getting  an  export  organization 
abroad  is  a  formidable  one.  The  small  size  of  many  foreign  markets, 
the  limited  number  of  dealers  available  in  contrast  to  the  domestic 
market,  and  the  established  reputation  of  certain  trade  names  all 
limit  the  number  of  firms  that  actually  do  an  extensive  export  busi- 
ness. For  these  reasons  the  position  of  a  company  that  is  established 
in  export  markets  is  more  secure  than  its  position  in  the  domestic 
market.  This  fact  suggests  why  advertising  and  selling  costs  are  a 
much  higher  proportion  of  domestic  sales  than  of  export  sales.  But 
whatever  the  reasons,  it  is  clear  that  competition  by  domestic  pro- 
ducers in  these  industries  is  a  more  effective  regulator  of  price  in 
the  United  States  than  in  many  foreign  markets.  Another  important 
factor  from  the  company's  sta'.dpoint  is  that  in  the  domestic  market 
there  are  models  priced  for  almost  every  type  of  buyer.  The  relation 
between  purchasing  power  and  price  is  such  that  this  product  has 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  g^ 

achieved  mass  distribution.  This  is  hardly  possible  in  most  foreign 
markets  to  which  the  company  exports.  Total  landed  costs  make  the 
retail  price  much  higher  than  in  the  United  States  and  low  purchasing 
power  makes  the  product  somewhat  of  a  luxury  item.  Such  a  con- 
dition militates  against  price  reductions. 

At  the  same  time  the  difference  between  domestic  and  export  list 
prices  for  identical  models  must  be  kept  rather  narrow  or  this  busi- 
ness would  soon  fall  into  the  hands  of  the  domestic  distributors. 
While  they  are  not  at  present  equipped  to  handle  exports  they  WDuld 
soon  establish  the  necessary  marketing  organizations  if  the  price 
differentials  were  wide  enough  to  make  it  attractive. 

It  is  of  great  importance  to  note  that  the  differing  intensity  of  price 
competition  in  the  domestic  and  export  markets  is  not  only  a  matter 
of  the  number  of  manufacurers  selling  in  those  markets.  The  variety 
of  distribution  channels  in  the  domestic  market  and  competition 
among  the  various  types  of  retail  outlets  puts  considerable  pressure 
on  the  manufacturer  to  offer  his  product  at  a  price  that  can  meet  the 
competition.  The  initiative  taken  by  certain  mass-distribution  organ- 
izations in  procuring  lower-priced  products  in  the  industries  under 
consideration  are  well-known  examples  of  the  competitive  business 
created  in  this  way. 

The  same  thing  is  observable  within  the  single  manufacturing  or- 
ganization described  in  example  30.  The  new  channels  of  distribution 
that  have  grown  up  and  captured  a  large  share  of  the  domestic  busi- 
ness have  forced  this  company  to  manufacture  for  those  price  mar- 
kets. On  its  chain-store  line,  5-  and  10-cent  line,  or  private  brands, 
prices  are  decidedly  lower  than  export  prices.  It  is  true  that  only  the 
branded  line  is  sold  in  export,  but  the  brand  is  of  no  great  significance 
as  it  is  not  advertised  abroad.  There  is  no  telling  what  the  company's 
export  policy  would  be  if  it  had  the  same  kind  of  price  competition 
from  5-  and  10-cent  stores  and  chain  stores  abroad  as  it  has  here. 

Another  consideration  that  may  lead  to  a  higher  export  price,  while 
not  clearly  exhibited  in  any  of  the  group  I  cases,  is  illustrated  in 
examples  26  and  27  of  group  III.  We  have  in  those  examples  com- 
panies that  sell  a  large  share  of  their  export  shipments  at  lower  than 
domestic  prices,  but  for  some  products  get  a  higher  price  on  export 
sales.  The  reason  for  the  higher  export  prices  is  that  the  products  are 
designed  for  a  particular  price  class  in  the  domestic  market.  The 
products  in  the  examples  are  $0.25,  $1,  and  $1.50  "sellers"  at  retail 
throughout  the  United  States.  But  while  these  price  classes  have 
meaning  for  the  domestic  market  they  have  no  particular  meaning  in 
foreign  markets  when  converted  into  a  price  in  local  currency.  The 
export  price  can,  therefore,  be  adjusted  to  fit  local  market  conditions 
and  in  these  cases  local  market  conditions  make  a  higher  price  more 
profitable  for  the  company.  There  are  other  cases,  discussed  later  in 
the  chapter,  in  which  local  market  conditions  or  a  foreign  price  class 
make  a  lower  export  price  necessary. 

WHAT  VOLUME  OF  EXPORT  TRADE  IS  SOLD  AT  HIGHER  THAN  DOMESTIC  PRICES? 

After  reviewing  the  cases  with  higher  export  prices  and  the  prob- 
able explanation  of  the  price  differences  a  question  naturally  arises 
as  to  the  quantitative  importance  of  these  cases  in  our  export  trade. 

257769— 41— No.  6 6 


gg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

With  10  cases  out  of  the  sample  of  76  in  this  category  there  is  aji 
indication  that  a  not  insignificant  proportion  of  our  export  business 
in  manufactured  goods  is  done  at  higher  than  domestic  prices. 
What  then,  is  the  probable  proportion  of  exports  priced  higher  than 
similar  goods  in  the  domestic  market?  Is  the  proportion  indicated 
in  the  sample  an  exaggeration? 

It  is,  of  course,  impossible  to  answer  these  questions  with  any! 
statistical  validity  on  the  basis  of  the  present  study.  This  is  essen- 
tially a  case  study,  which  cannot  provide  quantitative  results.  How- 
ever, the  10  cases  of  group  I  are  not  merely  freaks  of  the  business 
world,  and  it  is  very  improbable  that  they  exaggerate  the  quantitative 
importance  of  higher  export  prices.  One  should  note  also  that  many 
of  the  cases  in  group  III  are  firms  that  sell  some  of  their  exports 
at  higher  prices,  and  many  other  companies  have  lower  selling  costs 
on  their  export  sales.  The  summary  table  at  the  beginning  of  this 
chapter  shows  that  18  cases  in  the  sample  find  export  business  more 
profitable  than  domestic  and  that  4  others  in  group  III  find  exports 
as  profitable  as  domestic  sales.  For  these  reasons  it  is  probable  that 
the  ratio  of  10  to  76  is  not  an  overstatement  of  the  area  of  higher 
export  prices;  quite  possibly  it  is  an  understatement  of  the  actual 
volume  of  export  sales  made  at  higher  prices  for  the  industries 
represented  in  the  survey.  The  writer  has  the  decided  impression, 
after  contact  with  many  individuals  in  the  export  business,  that 
higher  export  prices  are  not  limited  to  a  few  isolated  instances; 
they  are  of  quantitative  importance  in  the  total  volume  of  our  export 
trade  in  manufactured  goods. 

EXPORT  PRICSES   EQUAL   TO   DOMESTIC   PRICES 

There  seems  to  be  a  widespread  belief  that  the  normative  procedure 
of  a  producer  in  a  competitive  industry  is  to  sell  to  all  customers  at 
the  same  price  and  that  there  is,  therefore,  no  reason  why  export 
prices  should  be  any  different  from  domestic  prices.  The  rationale 
for  this  belief  derives  from  the  observable  facts  of  the  organized 
impersonal  markets  in  which  standardized  commodities  are  bought 
and  sold.  In  such  markets,  of  course,  the  seller  cannot  differentiate 
among  customers  because  the  transactions  are  arranged  by  a  third 
party  and  there  is  no  personal  contact  between  buyer  and  seller. 
Thus,  there  cannot  be  any  separation  of  domestic  and  foreign  buyers 
because  the  seller  cannot  control  the  destination  of  shipment. 

Leaving  aside  till  later  in  the  chapter  the  difficult  question  as  to 
when  an  industry  is  competitive,  it  should  be  observed  here  that 
where  goods  are  not  bought  and  sold  exclusively  on  an  organized 
market,  or  what  amounts  to  an  organized  market,  there  is  no  reason 
why,  from  the  mechanics  of  distribution  itself,  shipments  to  all  desti- 
nations must  be  made  at  the  same  net  price.  There  is  a  personal 
contract  between  the  seller  and  the  buyer  so  that  the  seller  can  quote 
a  special  price  for  a  particular  buyer  and  can  control  the  destination 
of  the  shipment.  ^  This  is  substantially  true  for  most  products  manu- 
factured by  the  firms  reviewed  in  this  survey.  The  management  in 
all  these  cases  could  adopt  export  prices  that  differed  from  their 
domestic  prices  if  they  considered  it  desirable  to  do  so.  In  a  sense, 
therefore,  all  the  companies  in  group  II  whose  export  and  domestic 
prices  are  the  same  have  adopted  a  conscious  price  policy  just  as 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  59 

much  as  the  companies  that  have  different  domestic  and  export 
prices.  From  the  objective  standpoint  domestic  and  export  prices 
can  be  unequal  just  as  well  as  equal.  Hence,  there  must  be  reasons 
for  the  price  policy  in  either  case.  The  one  type  of  policy  is  no  more 
normative  than  the  other  for  all  goods  not  traded  in  organized 
markets  or  their  equivalent — well-informed  groups  of  buyers  or  sellers 
with  about  the  same  bargaining  strength. 

It  was  with  this  p6int  in  view  that  the  firms  in  group  II  were  asked 
why  they  adhered  to  a  policy  of  identical  domestic  and  export  prices. 
The  following  list  represents  the  investigator's  interpretation  of  the 
reasons  given  for  equal  domestic  and  exj)ort  prices  in  these  cases. 

1.  In  a  few  cases  involving  standardized  commodities  the  manage- 
ment believes  that  any  other  than  domestic  prices  that  could  actually 
be  obtained  in  export  would  be  less  profitable.  Higher  export  prices 
are  impossible  because  foreign  buyers  know  the  domestic  market  well 
and  can  always  find  firms  willing  to  sell  at  the  domestic  market  price. 
Lower  export  prices  would  be  unprofitable  because  the  trading  profit 
margin  is  small,  and  unnecessary  because  a  price  concession  in  the 
domestic  market  for  the  purpose  of  disposing  of  merchandise  is  just 
as  effective  as  in  export  markets. 

2.  Foreign  buyers  often  come  to  the  United  States  on  buying  trips 
and  visit  the  salesrooms  of  the  company,  so  higher  export  prices  would 
cause  a  great  deal  of  trouble.  Again,  the  company  does  not  have  to 
sell  at  lower  prices — it  could  do  that  in  the  United  States.  Several 
other  firms  also  said  they  were  not  interested  in  exports  if  they  could 
not  get  their  price. 

3.  The  management  in  a  few  cases  stated  that  the  domestic  price  was 
too  well  known  to  be  altered  for  export  customers. 

4.  Price  concessions  were  experimented  with  in  1931  and  1932  when 
many  foreign  dealers  were  hard  hit  by  exchange  depreciations.  The 
company  states  that  it  had  so  much  trouble  with  those  concessions  that 
it  does  not  intend  to  give  any  again. 

5.  One  company  states  that  its  products  must  sell  on  their  efficiency. 
Price  is  a  relatively  minor  matter  if  they  have  the  best  equipment  for 
the  job.  Failing  this,  no  price  concession  that  the  company  could 
afford  to  give  would  help  make  the  sale.  The  company  has  never  tried 
to  get  a  higher  price  in  export  because  it  is  satisfied  to  get  the  domestic 
price. 

6.  In  a  few  cases  it  is  obvious  that  the  management  has  never  drawn 
a  distinction,  even  in  its  own  mind,  between  domestic  and  export  cus- 
tomers. A  one-price  system  is  followed  as  a  matter  of  policy.  Differ- 
ent prices  to  different  types  of  customers  have  been  contemplated  but 
never  on  the  basis  of  domestic  or  export  shipment.  That  distinction 
has  no  meaning  for  the  business  of  these  firms. 

7.  Most  of  the  firms  maintain  equal  prices  to  all  customers  as  a  mat- 
ter of  policy  because  that  policy  conforms  to  their  conception  of  ethi- 
cal business  practice.  They  seem  to  feel  that  it  would  be  unfair  to 
their  domestic  customers  to  sell  abroad  at  lower  prices  and  unfair  to 
their  foreign  customers  to  ask  them  a  higher  price.  They  think  that 
sound  business  must  be  built  upon  fair  dealing  and  that  is  interpreted 
to  mean  an  identical  price  for  all  customers. 

8.  A  reason  for  equal  domestic  and  export  prices  given  by  some  of 
the  group  III  cases  should  be  mentioned  here.  The  firms  are  willing 
and  often  do  adjust  prices  to  fit  conditions  in  tie  given  export  market, 


70 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


but  if  they  have  no  special  knowledge  of  local  market  conditions  they 
simply  quote  domestic  prices  and  take  whatever  business  comes.  It 
seems  to  the  investigator  that  this  is  also  the  real  reason  why  domestic 
and  export  prices  are  equal  in  some  of  the  group  II  cases.  Firms 
selling  the  large  bulk  of  their  output  in  the  domestic  market  establish 
their  price  schedules  to  fit  domestic  market  conditions.  Export  sales 
are  a  byproduct  to  domestic  operations.  The  firms  are  not  making  an 
intensive  effort  to  get  export  business,  and  they  frequently  do  not  have 
an  intimate  knowledge  of  market  conditions  in  foreign  countries.  In 
many  eases,  being  in  the  export  business  only  means  that  the  firms  have 
established  some  sales  contacts  abroad.  They  do  not  know  enough 
about  conditions  abroad  to  price  specifically  for  local  market.  Such  is 
often  the  policy  of  companies  that  export  a  small  proportion  of  their 
output. 

The  8  reasons  given  above  for  identical  domestic  and  export  prices 
also  apply  to  that  part  of  export  sales  of  the  group  III  cases  for 
which  prices  are  the  same  as  domestic  prices.  It  should  be  evident 
that  the  volume  of  exports  at  prices  equal  to  domestic  prices  is  much 
greater  than  could  be  inferred  from  the  fact  that  only  21  cases  out  of 
76  were  in  group  II.  In  many  of  the  group  I  and  group  III  cases  a 
large  part  of  export  sales  are  at  domestic  prices.  It  is  probable  that 
the  volume  of  exports  for  which  prices  are  equal  to  domestic  prices  is 
larger  than  the  volume  sold  at  lower  prices. 

EXPORT  PRICES. LOWER  THAN   DOMESTIC  PRICES 

The  following  discussion  is  devoted  to  explaining  why  prices  for 
export  in  many  cases  are  lower  than  domestic  prices.  There  are 
various  aspects  of  this  problem. 

1.  Why  the  management  of  a  firm  is  willing  to  make  price  conces- 
sions on  export  sales. 

2.  The  factors  in  foreign  market  conditions  that  necessitate  price 
concessions. 

3.  Why  higher  domestic  than  export  prices  are  possible. 

a.  The  monopoly  aspects  of  the  problem. 
h.  The  influence  of  tariff  protection. 

c.  The  difference  between  the  selling  problem  in  the  domestic 
market  and  that  in  foreign  markets. 

d.  The  influence  of  disequilibrium  conditions. 

4.  Other  factors  influencing  export-price  policy. 

While  these  factors  will  be  discussed  separately,  a  complete  ex- 
planation involves  all  of  them. 

1.  Why  Is  a  Firm  Willing  To  Grant  Price  Concessions  on  Export 
Shipments  f 
In  any  analysis  of  the  price  mechanism  it  must  be  assumed  that  in 
business  operations  undertaken  for  a  profit  the  aim  of  management 
is  always  to  make  profits  as  large  as  possible  with  the  economic 
resources  at'  its  command.  The  problem  in  every  business  is  to  find 
the  volume-price  relationship  which  will  yield  the  greatest  net  return 
above  the  costs  of  producing  that  volume  of  output.  Where  the  pro- 
ducer has  no  option  but  to  sell  at  the  market  price  and  any  possible 
output  that  he  might  produce  is  too  small  to  have  a  significant  in- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER  'J^ 

fluence  on  the  market  price  then  the  relation  between  costs  and  the 
volume  of  his  production  offers  the  only  control  he  has  over  the  profit- 
ability of  his  operations.  But  where  the  producer  can  get  some  sales 
at  a  series  of  prices  or  where  he  knows  that  the  volume  of  his  produc- 
tion has  a  significant  influence  on  the  price  then  he  has  also  the  price 
variable  to  consider  in  finding  his  most  profitable  scale  of  operations. 

The  point  is  that  for  any  given  volume  of  output  a  producer  wants 
to  get  as  high  a  price  as  possible  since  that  will  maximize  his  profit — 
with  the  proviso,  of  course,  that  he  will  not  exploit  a  temporary  situa- 
tion to  the  full  if  such  conduct  is  likely  to  result  in  less  profitable 
operations  in  the  future.  A  firm  is  willing  to  grant  a  price  concession 
in  a  particular  market,  therefore,  only  because  it  has  no  alternative 
market  in  which  it  could  obtain  a  higher  price  for  that  part  of  its 
output  in  addition  to  its  existing  receipts  from  each  market  and  be- 
cause its  total  operations  would  be  less  profitable  if  it  were  to  forego 
that  business  at  lower  prices.  Once  again  it  is  the  profitability  of 
the  business  in  the  long  run  that  is  the  dominant  consideration. 

Among  the  46  cases  of  group  III  in  this  study  the  following  reasons 
were  given  as  to  why  the  lower  export  prices  currently  in  effect  in- 
crease the  profitability  of  operations.  It  is  not  feasible  in  outlining 
these  reasons  to  indicate  the  number  of  cases  which  mentioned  each 
one  because  the  answers  to  any  inquiry  of  this  type  vary  considerably 
with  the  articulateness  of  the  executive  interviewed  rather  than  with 
the  actual  considerations  behind  the  price  policy.  As  the  investigator 
was  making  every  effort  to  allow  the  executive  to  make  his  own  case 
and  not  to  interject  suggestions  which  might  merely  provide  a  ration- 
alization for  the  price  policy,  only  meager  responses  were  obtained  in 
several  cases  on  this  problem.  However,  each  of  the  following  reasons 
were  given  in  at  least  2  of  the  46  cases.  The  exports  referred  to 
below  are  only  those  which  are  sold  at  lower  prices : 

(a)  Many  of  the  cases  stated  that  any  attempt  to  sell  the  lower- 
priced  exports  in  the  domestic  market  would  be  possible  only  at  less 
profitable  prices  for  the  entire  output.  Even  though  the  domestic 
market  might  absorb  the  exports  at  the  lower  export  price  or  perhaps 
at  a  smaller  price  reduction  than  is  now  given  in  export,  the  conse- 
quence of  reducing  the  price  on  the  existing  large  volume  of  domestic 
sales  would  lower  gross  receipt  from  sales  on  total  output  and  hence 
make  the  business  less  profitable.  In  other  words,  it  would  not  pay  to 
break  the  domestic  price. 

(5)  Quite  a  few  of  the  cases  believe  that  the  domestic  market  is 
absorbing  as  much  of  the  products  as  is  practically  possible  and 
that  no  feasible  reductions  in  the  domestic  price  would  appreciably 
increase  the  volume  sold.  It  is  their  belief  that  the  domestic  demand 
is  highly  inelastic  and  consequently  there  is  no  further  outlet  in  the 
domestic  market. 

(c)  In  many  cases  it  was  stated  that  while  some  export  sales  would 
be  possible  at  the  domestic  price,  the  lower  export  price  results  in  so 
large  an  increase  in  sales  that  total  profit  on  exports  is  enhanced. 

(d)  Others  consider  foreign  market  conditions  such  that  no  sales 
(in  that  particular  market  or  in  all  markets  as  the  case  might  be) 
are  possible  at  domestic  prices.  By  giving  a  price  concession  they 
get  some  sales  and  while  the  margin  of  profit  is  less  than  on  domestic 
sales  the  exports  are  still  profitable. 


72  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

{e)  In  some  cases  the  export  price  does  not  cover  full  costs  but  it 
does  cover  factory  costs  and  part  of  the  overhead  and  thus  reduces 
the  burden  on  domestic  sales. 

(/)  In  other  cases  it  was  stated  that  the  increased  volume  obtained 
by  the  export-price  reduction  lowers  the  average  manufacturing  costs. 
The  exports  are,  therefore,  profitable  even  if  prices  only  cover  out- 
of-pocket  costs  involved  in  the  transaction  as  the  profitability  of 
domestic  sales  is  thereby  enhanced.  It  should  be  noted  that  this  is 
not  a  universal  proposition  as  some  firms  find  that  filling  export  orders 
often  increases  manufacturing  costs.  These  are  cases  with  diversified 
lines  of  products  all  of  which  are  not  manufactured  simultaneously. 
When  export  orders  do  not  fit  in  with  the  domestic  production  schedule 
the  cost  of  both  export  and  domestic  manufacture  is  increased. 

(g)  Some  stated  that  the  volume  that  could  be  absorbed  by  the 
domestic  market  would  not  provide  reasonably  full  employment  for 
their  labor  and  that  without  exports  labor  turnover  would  be  much 
larger.  As  the  cost  of  training  new  hands  is  very  high  (over  $150  in 
one  case)  it  pays  to  continue  exporting  even  though  exports  show  a 
book  loss. 

(k)  Several  of  the  firms  stated  that  they  sell  a  few  items  in  their 
lines  at  a  lower  profit,  or  at  a  loss,  because  it  enables  them  to  sell 
other  items  on  which  they  get  the  full  domestic  price  or  more.  These 
are  cases  in  which  the  foreign  distributor  requires  a  full  line  in  order 
to  stay  in  business  or  to  increase  his  sales  to  a  more  profitable  level 
for  the  American  producer. 

(i)  It  was  quite  frequently  claimed  that  the  price  reductions  were 
made  for  the  purpose  af  tiding  over  a  temporary  situation  due  to 
depressed  business  conditions  in  a  particular  country  or  to  a  de- 
preciation of  the  exchange.  The  company  did  not  want  to  withdraw 
from  the  market  as  it  had  an  investment  tied  up  in  it  in  development 
costs.  It  was  felt  that  a  return  on  that  investment  would  again  be 
possible  and  profitable  business  in  that  market  would  come  back  if 
only  the  dealers  could  be  maintained  in  business  and  the  product 
kept  before  the  public  in  the  interim.  It  should  be  apparent  that 
these  factors  are  not  independent  but  are  interrelated  in  determining 
a  firm's  price  policy. 

^.  Factors  in  Foreign  Market  Conditions  Which  Necessitate  Lower 
Export  Prices. 

The  discussion  above  may  be  summarized  merely  by  saying  tliat  a 
firm  exporting  at  lower  than  domestic  prices  does  so  because  its  total 
operations  are  more  profitable  with  those  export  sales  than  without 
them.  Once  this  point  is  recognized  it  is  pertinent  to  ask  why  it  is 
that  export  prices  equal  to  domestic  prices  cannot  be  obtained  in 
some  or  all  export  markets.  What  conditions  are  there  in  the  foreign- 
market  situation  different  from  the  domestic  which  make  lower  ex- 
port prices  necessary?  These  are  the  conditions,  one  might  say, 
which  the  management  is  attempting  to  overcome  by  a  price  conces- 
sion. Tlie  following  factors  were  all  mentioned  by  the  46  cases  of 
the  sample  which  are  currently  exporting  at  lower  than  domestic 
prices. 

(a)  The  existence  of  foreign  competition  of  similar  goods  priced 
lower  than  American  products   is  the   factor  most  often   cited   as 


CM3N0ENTRATI0N  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  73 

necessitating  a  lower  export  price.  In  some  cases  it  is  locally  made 
products  and  in  others  it  is  imported  products  from  other  countries 
competing  with  United  States  merchandise  in  third  markets.  It  was 
frequently  stated  that  while  the  American  product  is  of  superior 
quality  and  can  command  a  higher  price  than  foreign-made  goods 
the  differential  cannot  be  as  great  as  would  be  required  if  the 
products  were  exported  at  domestic  prices. 

(b)  A  few  firms  have  lower  export  prices  for  particular  foreign 
markets  in  order  to  meet  the  price  competition  of  other  United  States 
producers  who  are  attempting  to  enlarge  their  share  of  the  market. 
United  States  competition  was  cited  much  less  often  than  foreign  com- 
petition as  the  reason  for  lower  export  prices. 

(c)  Quite  similar  to  the  existence  of  lower-priced  competing  prod- 
ucts are  the  cases  in  which  the  producer  lowers  his  price  to  particular 
markets  in  order  that  his  product  may  be  sold  in  the  conventional  price 
class  in  the  currenc}^  of  those  markets.  This  is  an  important  market- 
ing consideration  for  many .  type3  of  novelty  consumers'  goods.  A 
product  is  made  to  sell  for  10  cents,  50  cents,  or  a  dollar  in  the  domestic 
market  regardless  of  the  fact  that  there  are  somewhat  similar  prod- 
ucts selling  at  other  prices.  The  vagaries  of  the  consumer  are  such 
that  many  quite  similar  products  are  sold  in  the  same  store  at  a 
variety  of  prices.  The  American  producer  might  know  that  his  (say) 
25-cent  seller  would  go  over  better  in  foreign  markets  if  the  price  in 
local  currency  was  (say)  5  pesos  (Chilean),  1  krona  (Swedish),  and  5 
milreis.  He,  therefore,  lowers  the  export  price  to  those  countries  to 
enable  the  foreign  dealer  to  sell  at  those  price^s. 

(d)  Lower  export  prices  are  often  established  because  the  high 
landed  costs  to  the  importer  would  otherwise  raise  the  price  in  the 
foreign  country  above  a  salable  level.  High  tariffs  is  the  cost  item 
most  frequently  cited,  but  ocean  freight  costs  is  also  an  important 
factor.  These  factors  can  be  operative  even  if  there  is  no  local  compe- 
tition with  lower  prices  which  must  be  met. 

(e)  Export  prices  are  often  lowered  to  put  the  product  within  the 
reach  of  a  people  with  low  purchasing  power.  The  relatively  high 
average  income  level  in  the  United  States  allows  the  firm  to  sell  at  the 
domestic  price,  but  that  price  would  put  the  product  beyond  the 
means  of  most  of  the  consumer3  in  countries  with  a  much  lower 
average  income. 

(/)  Price  concessions  are  given  in  order  that  the  foreign  distributor 
or  dealer  might  have  a  gross-profit  margin  large  enough  to  keep  him 
in  business.  This  is  often  necessary  in  markets  where  the  volume  of 
gales  is  low  in  comparison  with  the  sales  volume  of  a  dealer  or  dis- 
tributor in  the  American  market.  The  retail  price  cannot  be  any 
higher  abroad  than  it  is  here,  so  the  American  producer  must  absorb 
some  of  the  foreign  agent's  high  unit  costs  of  operating  in  his  market, 
his  high  unit  costs  being  due  to  small  volume. 

(g)  Another  form  of  essentially  the  same  situation  is  found  in  cases 
where  a  company  gives  an  allowance  to  its  foreign  representative  to 
cover  his  costs  in  supplying  services  required  in  the  marketing  of  the 
product.  The  small  volume  of  sales  in  the  foreign  market  raises  the 
service  costs  per  unit  much  above  the  company's  own  costs  in  the 
domestic  market  so  that  the  allowance  given  is  equivalent  to  a  price 
reduction. 


74  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(A)  A  factor  very  frequently  cited  as  requiring  lower  export  prices 
is  the  depreciation  of  foreign  currencies.  Such  depreciation  would 
automatically  rai^e  the  local  currency  price  if  the  same  dollar  export 
price  were  maintained.  Since  the  market  cannot  stand  the  higher 
price,  because  the  prices  of  locally  made  goods  do  not  rise,  or  the 
product  has  become  established  in  the  market  at  a  certain  local  currency 
price,  or  the  rise  would  take  the  product  out  of  its  price  class,  etc., 
the  dollar  export  price  must  be  lowered. 

(i)  The  general  business  situation  is  not  the  same  in  all  coun- 
tries at  the  same  time.  While  business  is  depressed  and  prices  low 
in  some  markets,  trade  is  active  and  prices  strong  m  other  markets. 
A  producer  selling  in  many  markets  must  adjust  prices  to  meet  local 
business  conditions.  This  is  particularly  the  case  where  the  bulk 
of  producers  in  each  market  do  only  a  local  business  while  a  few 
firms  are  active  on  an  international  scale. 

S.  Why  Domestic  Prices  Are  Higher. 

It  is  evident  that  the  factors  in  foreign  market  conditions  cited 
above  as  the  reasons  for  United  States  firms  selling  in  export  at 
lower  than  domestic  prices  could  all  be  reversed  to  explain  why 
they  sell  at  higher  prices  in  the  domestic  market.  That  much  is 
implicit  in  the  factors  themselves;  they  do  have  importance  in 
foreign  markets  and  they  do  not  have  importance  in  the  domestic 
market.  The  domestic  pricf  is  higher  because  these  factors  are  not 
present  to  induce  the  prodi  ;er  to  make  them  lower.  The  question 
at  issue  then  becomes:  What  enables  these  producers  to  maintain 
price  differentials,  to  get  higher  domestic  than  export  prices? 

A.  Monopoly  aspects  of  the  problem. — This  leads  to  the  funda- 
mental problem  of  our  study.  Does  the  existence  of  lower  export 
than  domestic  prices  imply  that  competition  in  the  domestic  market 
is  in  some  way  restricted,  that  the  producer  to  some  extent  is  in  a 
monopolistic  position?  Can  competition  and  price  differences  exist 
side  by  side,  or  are  the  two  conditions  incompatible? 

In  order  to  answer  this  question  it  is  necessary  to  reach  an  under- 
standing of  the  meaning  to  be  attached  to  the  term  competition. 
The  business  practices  implicit  in  competition  must  be  distinguished 
from  those  associated  with  monopoly  in  order  to  decide  whether  a 
business  or  an  industry  is  competitive  or  monopolistic. 

The  popular  conception  of  competition,  held  by  most  business  men 
and  by  the  general  public,  may  be  defined  as  the  independent  rivalry 
of  a  number  of  producers  of  a  rather  similar  product  for  the  busi- 
ness patronage  of  the  consumers  of  that  product.  The  essential 
elements  of  this  conception  are  that  there  are  several  producers 
engaged  in  the  production  of  the  commodity  and  that  they  act 
independently  in  setting  their  price,  production,  and  selling  poli- 
cies. Each  uses  his  own  judgment  as  to  how  much  to  produce, 
what  price  to  charge,  and  how  to  reach  the  consumer.  Each  tries 
to  get  as  large  a  share  of  the  market  as  he  profitably  can. 

As  opposed  to  a  condition  of  competition,  there  is  generally  con- 
ceived to  be  a  condition  of  monopoly  in  which  the  essential  elements 
of  competition  are  not  operative.  Either  the  total  production  of 
the  commodity  is  in  the  hands  of  one  business  organization,  or  else 
there  is  an  agreement — tacit  or  explicit — among  the  several  pro- 
ducers of  the  commodity  to  maintain  prices,  limit  production,  or 


(X)NOENTRATI0N  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  75 

allocate  market  areas.  Competition  and  monopoly  are  looked  upon 
as  alternative  forms  of  business  activity  and  mutually  exclusive 
categories  of  business  behavior;  an  industry  is  either  competitive  or 
monopolistic.  To  a  large  extent,  antitrust  legislation  is  based  upon 
this  conception.  It  seeks  to  prohibit  actions  by  business  which  limit 
independent  rivalry  for  trade  except  insofar  as  those  limitations 
arise  from  patents,  copyright,  or  regulated  monopolies. 

A  little  reflection  will  convince  one  that  this  dichotomy  does  not 
accurately  describe  the  price-making  process.  It  is  evident  that  many 
kinds  of  marketing  procedures  and  situations  are  possible  under  such 
an  all-embracing  competition :  the  competition  may  be  more  or  less 
severe  and  may  take  many  different  forms.  The  monopoly,  too,  may 
be  more  or  less  restrictive. 

For  this  reason  the  economist  attempts  to  be  more  analytical  in 
defining  competition.  As  his  interest  is  in  describing  the  price-mak- 
ing process  as  accurately  as  possible,  he  seeks  all  the  gradations  in 
competition  and  the  differences  in  degree  from  one  type  to  another. 
He  tries  to  get  at  the  essence  of  competition  by  describing  the  com- 
petitive process  in  its  purest  form. 

A  condition  of  unrestricted  competition  may  be  called  pure  com- 
petition. An  examination  of  tlie  few  productive  areas  in  our  eco- 
nomic system  in  which  competitive  forces  are  almost  entirely  unim- 
peded reveals  that  two  conditions  are  necessary  for  pure  competition. 
The  first  is  that  there  be  a  large  number  of  buyers  and  sellers  in  the 
market.    The  second  is  that  the  product  be  highly  standardized. 

What  constitutes  a  large  number  of  buyers  and  sellers?  In  this 
context  a  large  number  of  buyers  and  sellers  is  one  large  enough  to 
deny  to  the  sales  or  purchases  of  anyone  a  significant  influence  on 
price.  The  amount  demanded  or  amount  offered  by  each  buyer  or 
seller  must  be  so  small  with  relation  to  the  total  market  that  what- 
ever decision  he  makes  as  to  buying  or  selling  will  not  affect  the 
market  price.    Thus,  for  each,  the  market  price  is  an  objective  fact. 

When  is  a  product  highly  standardized?  That  condition  is  ful- 
filled when  the  output  of  any  producer  is  so  similar  to  that  of  other 
producers  that  the  buyers  are  indifferent  as  to  which  they  get.  They 
will  not  pay  a  higher  price  for  any  particular  seller's  product. 

Under  these  conditions  no  one  producer  or  buyer  can  influence  the 
market  price.  Although  the  decisions  of  the  sellers  and  buyers  col- 
lectively determine'  the  price,  that  price  is  beyond  the  control  of  any 
one  of  them.  The  producer  has  many  decisions  to  make  under  these 
conrlitions,  but  in  all  of  them  he  takes  the  market  price  as  an  objec- 
tive fact  over  which  he  has  no  control.  Regardless  of  how  much  he 
decides  to  produce  (within  extremely  wide  limits)  he  knows  that  he 
cannot  materially  alter  the  market  price. 

There  are,  in  our  economic  system,  only  a  few  commodities  pro- 
duced and  sold  under  conditio  .s  that  resemble  perfect  competition. 
Such  competition  is  restricv-ed  practically  to  a  few  grains  and  fibers 
which  are  sold  on  organized  commodity  exchanges. 

In  the  production  and  sale  of  most  commodities  these  conditions 
are  not  fulfilled  and  competition  is  not  pure,  particularly  over  short 
periods  of  time.  Either  the  number  of  producers  supplying  a  given 
market  is  relatively  small  or  the  product  is  not  highly  standardized 
or  both.  In  either  case  the  individual  producer  has  the  power  by  his 
decisions  to  influence  the  price  of  the  product.    If  the  number  of  pro- 


75  OONCENTRATION  OF  EOQNOMIC  POWER 

ducers  is  relatively  small  but  the  product  homogeneous  then  the  pro- 
ducer can  influence  the  price  by  the  quantity  he  produces.  If  the 
product  is  not  standardized  the  producer  may  influence  the  price  of 
his  product  by  catering  only  to  those  consumers  who  have  a  prefer- 
ence for  his  product.  It  should  be  observed  that  in  the  case  of  non- 
standardized  products  it  makes  little  difference  whether  each  producer 
is  considered  to  have  a  monopoly  over  his  output  or  whether  the 
competition  in  the  industry  is  considered  to  be  imperfect  or  monop- 
olistic competition. 

Thus,  from  an  objective  standpoint,  it  is  the  ability  of  a  single 
producer  to  influence  the  price  of  the  product  that  is  the  essence  of 
monopoly.  Whenever  a  producer  must  include  in  his  calculations  the 
effect  of  his  decisions  upon  price  he  is  not  operating  under  condi- 
tions of  pure  competition.  He  is  to  a  greater  or  lesser  extent  in  a 
monopolistic  position.  There  is  no  essential  difference  between  his 
having  to  calculate  the  quantity  he  will  sell  at  the  various  prices  he 
can  quote  or  the  market  price  which  will  result  from  the  various  quan- 
tities he  can  produce.  In  either  case  he  recognizes  that  the  quantity 
of  his  output  and  the  price  he  can  get  are  interrelated — he  is  able 
to  recognize  the  slope  of  the  demand  curve  for  the  products  of  his 
firm. 

It  will  be  evident  that  the  departure  from  conditions  of  pure  com- 
petition is  a  gradual  one ;  that  is,  that  the  monopoly  element  is  present 
to  a  greater  or  lesser  extent  in  actual  economic  life  as  the  conditions 
of  perfect  competition  are  more  or  less  relaxed.  Other  things  being 
equal,  the  fewer  the  number  of  independent  producers  and  the  more 
distinctive  the  product  of  each,  the  greater  is  their  possible  effect  upon 
price  and  the  greater  their  monopoly  position.  Likewise,  the  larger 
the  number  of  producers  and  the  more  homogenous  the  product,  the 
more  nearly  is  the  condition  of  pure  competition  approached.  In 
other  words,  competition  or  monopoly  is  a  matter  of  degree.  Starting 
from  pure  competition  market  situations  may  be  less  and  less  competi- 
tive as  the  powers  of  the  individual  producer  over  price  increase. 

On  the  other  hand  it  must  be  recognized  that  there  is  no  such 
condition  as  perfect  monopoly  at  the  other  end  of  the  scale  opposite 
pure  competition.  The  monopoly  power  is  the  power  to  affect  price 
and  there  is  no  producer  who  has  that  power  to  an  absolute  degree. 
That  power  is  always  circumscribed  by  competing  products,  by  other 
means  of  satisfying  the  same  wants,  or  by  the  consumer's  alternative 
desires.  There  is  no  single  economic  good  that  we  cannot  do  without 
if  the  price  is  set  too  high.  Therefore,  even  if  one  producer  controls 
the  output  of  a  commodity  his  monopoly  power  cannot  be  infinitely 
great.  Monopoly,  or  competition  for  that  matter,  is  purely  a  question 
of  degree.  The  greater  the  power  to  affect  price  the  greater  the 
monopoly  power  and  the  less  the  competition. 

Now  under  conditions  of  or  even  closely  approximating  pure  com- 
petition it  would  obviously  be  unprofitable  for  a  producer  to  export  at 
prices  below  the  domestic  market  price.  For  he  is  in  a  position  to 
sell  as  much  as  he  can  without  perceptibly  lowering  the  domestic  price. 
If  a  part  of  the  domestic  output  were  being  exported  at  the  domestic 
price  and  the  foreign  price  declined  then  the  producers  would  im- 
mediately shift  their  sales  to  the  domestic  market  until  the  two 
prices  were  again  equal.  It  would  not  pay  any  one  of  them  to  con- 
tinue exporting  at  less  than  the  domestic  price.    It  can  be  said,  there- 


CXDNCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  77 

fore,  that  under  conditions  of  pure  competition  price  discrimination 
among  markets  by  a  single  producer  is  impossible. 

But  once  the  degree  of  competition  is  somewhat  restricted,  once  an 
element  of  monopoly  is  introduced,  then  exporting  at  less  than  the 
domestic  price  may  be  profitable  and,  therefore,  is  apt  to  arise.  It  is 
precisely  this  and  only  this  that  should  be  implied  by  saying  that 
monopoly  is  a  necessary  condition  for  dumping  (selling  for  export  at 
lower  prices).  Dumping  and  pure  competition  are  incompatible  con- 
ditions and  cannot  exist  side  by  side.  The  existence  of  dumping  is 
thus  prima  facie  evidence  that  competition  is  somewhat  restricted, 
that  some  element  of  monopoly  from  an  economic  standpoint  is  present. 

This  does  not  mean  that  competition  in  the  popular  or  legal  sense  ■ 
of  the  term  is  not  present.  There  may  be  independent  rivalry  for 
trade  among  the  producers  of  a  given  commodity  and  yet  the  condi- 
tion in  the  industry  be  far  from  pure  competition.  That  is,  lower 
export  prices  do  not  imply  necessarily  that  either  a  single  producer 
controls  the  output  of  a  commodity  or  that  the  several  producers  in 
the  industry  have  an  agreement  as  to  price  and  production  policies. 
The  mere  fact  that  competition  is  not  perfect  is  no  indication  that 
there  is  not  independent  action  by  all  producers  in  the  industry. 

This  distinction  between  pure  competition  in  the  economic  sense 
and  competition  in  the  "independent  rivalry  for  trade"  sense  is  not 
always  clearly  distinguished  in  discussions  of  the  dumping  problems. 
The  following  statement  shows  the  confusion  that  can  arise  on  this 
point. 

"A  necessary  condition  (for  dumping)  is  monopoly  upon  the  home 
market.  If  price  competition  in  the  strict  theoretical  sense  is  pres- 
ent— that  is  to  say  if  no  one  producer  can  perceptibly  influence  the 
price  of  his  product  so  that  each  producer  is  confronted  with  a  prac- 
tically horizontal  demand  curve — the  home  price  must  be  forced 
down.  The  monopoly  may  take  several  forms.  One  concern  may 
have  a  monopoly,  either  because  it  is  so  large  relative  to  the  market 
that  no  other  concern  can  profitably  enter  or  because  it  alone  has 
some  secret  process  of  production  or  possesses  a  patent  or  some  simi- 
lar legal  knowledge.  Several  producers  may  have  a  tacit  agreement 
or  may  be  explicitly  united  in  a  cartel  for  the  purpose  of  limiting 
the  amount  produced."  ^ 

In  the  first  part  of  this  statement  it  is  implied  that  monopoly  is  a 
situation  in  which  a  producer  can  perceptibly  influence  the  price  of 
his  product.  Price  competition  in  the  strict  theoretical  sense  is  per- 
fect competition,  and  anything  except  perfect  competition  is  monop- 
oly. Wlien  "a  single  producer  is  confronted  with  a  practically  hori- 
zontal demand  curve,"  it  means  that  he  can  dispose  of  all  his  output 
without  affecting  the  price  of  the  product. 

But  the  second  part  of  the  statement  implies  that  monopoly  is  a 
situation  in  which  either  one  producer  controls  the  entire  output  of 
the  product  or  the  several  producers  of  the  product  have  an  agree- 
ment to  limit  production.  The  implication  is  that  if  there  is  more 
than  one  producer  and  the  several  producers  do  not  have  an  agree- 
ment to  limit  production,  there  is  competition  in  the  industry. 

The  point  is  that  these  two  definitions  of  competition  and  monopoly 
are  not  the  same;  a  part  of  what  would  be  classed  as  monopolistic 

>  Gottfried  Von  Haberler,  The  Theory  of  International  Trade,  New  York,  1936,  pp. 
301-302. 


yg  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

conditions  under  the  one  would  be  competition  under  the  other. 
For  whenever  there  is  not  pure  competition  there  is  not  necessarily 
an  absence  of  independent  rivalry  for  trade.  There  can  be  restric- 
tions to  competition  without  total  output  being  controlled  by  a  single 
producer  or  Avithout  any  agreement  on  the  part  of  the  several  pro- 
ducers. While  industry  situations  of  this  type  have  been  described 
adequately  in  earlier  economic  literature,  they  have  been  given  more 
prominence  in  current  writing.^  These  situations  which  are  not 
pure  competition  and  not  monopoly  (in  the  popular  sense  of  the 
word)  have  been  called  imperfect  competition  or  monopolistic  com- 
petition. The  terms  are  used  to  describe  situations  in  which  a  pro- 
ducer has  some  power  (however  limited)  to  affect  the  price  of  his 
product  without  having  entered  into  a  tacit  or  explicit  agreement  to 
fix  prices  or  limit  production  with  other  producers  of  the  product. 

To  convince  himself  that  this  is  quite  possible  the  reader  need  only 
consider  the  position  of  the  producer  when  the  conditions  of  pure 
competition  are  relaxed;  when  monopolistic  competition  prevails. 
Those  conditions  were  (1)  that  there  be  a  large  number  of  producers 
and  (2)  that  the  product  be  highly  standardized. 

Consider  the  second  condition  first.  When  a  product  is  not  stand- 
ardized a  single  producer  may  have  some  control  over  the  price  of 
his  product  if  some  consumers  have  a  preference  for  it.  The  intro- 
duction of  brand  names,  trade-marks,  style  differences,  packaging, 
quality  differences,  the  reputation  of  the  firm,  the  type  of  appeal  used 
in  advertising  and  so  on  may  all  differentiate  one  producer's  goods 
from  that  of  another  and  result  in  different  prices  for  rather  similar 
products  within  the  same  marketing  area.  That  means  that  some  of 
the  producers  have  some  power  to  influence  the  price  of  their  prod- 
uct. For  one  reason  or  another  some  consumers  have  a  preference 
for  the  product  of  a  particular  firm  and  that  gives  the  firm  the  power 
to  get  a  higher  price  in  that  market. 

This  phenomenon  is  too  familiar  to  require  much  comment.  It  is 
well  known  that  in  many  consumer  goods  fields  the  products  of  the 
various  firms  are  differentiated  in  the  minds  of  the  buyers.  A  large 
variety  of  brands,  more  or  less  well  known,  are  available  at  quite 
different  prices.  A  producer  is  often  in  the  position  of  having  to 
decide  upon  a  price  and  marketing  policy  rather  than,  as  in  pure  com- 
petition, merely  selling  at  the  market  price. 

A  distinction  is  drawn  in  law  between  a  patent  and  a  brand  or 
trade-mark.  A  patent  is  conceived  as  conferring  a  monopoly  right 
whereas  a  brand  name  is  held  by  its  very  nature  to  imply  competition 
as  it  merely  differentiates  one's  product  from  that  of  his  competitors. 
This  distinction  may  be  important  for  certain  purposes  but  from  an 
economic  standpoint  it  is  not  important.  A  brand  name  may  make 
a  product  just  as  distinctive  in  the  mind  of  the  consumer  and  thus  as 
little  subject  to  price  competition  as  a  patented  product  for  which 
there  are  many  substitutes.  And,  as  has  been  pointed  out,  it  is  just 
as  logical  to  say  that  each  producer  of  a  branded  product  has  a 
monopoly  of  his  brand  as  to  say  that  there  is  monopolistic  competi- 
tion among  brands.  Of  course,  this  does  not  mean  that  the  mere 
brandmg  of  a  product  will  differentiate  it  in  the  mind  of  the  con- 
sumer.   But  it  may,  and  very  often  does. 

Th/^r'^"'Y^y  E    Chamberlain,  The  Theory  of  Monopolistic  Competition,  and  J.  Robinson, 
ine  Economics  of  Imperfect  Competition. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  79 

Under  a  condition  of  monopolistic  competition  of  this  type  there 
is  no  reason  why  the  domestic  and  export  prices  of  any  particular 
producer  must  be  equal.  Even  though  the  producer  has  competitors 
making  somewhat  similar  products  and  even  though  he  is  not  in 
collusion  with  them  to  maintain  domestic  prices  his  export  price  may 
be  lower  than  his  domestic  price.  He  may  have  a  reputation  in  the 
domestic  market  that  enables  him  to  get  a  higher  price  than  his 
competitors  and  not  have  a  superior  reputation  in  foreign  markets. 
He  may  be  directing  his  appeal  to  a  higher  income  group  in  the 
domestic  market  while  in  certain  foreign  countries  there  is  no  such 
income  group  large  enough  to  constitute  a  market.  The  American 
consumer  may  be  willing  to  pay  a  premium  for  the  higher  quality 
he  offers  but  the  foreign  consumer  may  value  that  quality  less  highly. 
His  styling  may  be  particularly  designed  for  American  tastes  and 
that  may  enable  him  to  get  a  higher  price  at  home  than  abroad. 
In  all  these  circumstances  it  is  economically  correct  to  say  that  the 
producer  has  a  monopolistic  position  in  the  domestic  market  which 
he  does  not  have  (at  least  to  the  same  extent)  in  the  foreign  market. 

A  somewhat  similar  situation  results  wh-^.n  the  other  condition  of 
pure  competition  is  relaxed;  that  is,  when  there  is  a  small  number 
of  producers  in  relation  to  the  size  of  the  market.  The  number  of 
producers  is  small  when  each  of  them  or  some  of  them  are  able  to 
influence  the  price  by  a  change  in  the  scale  of  their  operations.  Quite 
often  product  differentiation  and  fewness  of  producers  are  present 
together  and  supplement  each  other  in  injecting  a  monopolistic  ele- 
ment in  the  market  situation.  But  there  are  many  cases  where  the 
products  of  the  various  firms  are  very  similar  and  the  fewness  of 
producers  alone  creates  an  imperfectly  competitive  situation. 

Under  monopolistic  competition  of  this  type  the  producer  must 
calculate  the  effect  upon  price  of  any  change  in  the  scale  of  his 
operations  and  hence  the  effect  upon  his  total  profit.  He  cannot 
merely  produce  to  the  full  extent  of  his  resources  and  expect  that 
the  price  will  remain  unchanged.  The  products  of  all  the  firms  will 
sell  in  the  market  at  the  same  price  but  each  or  some  of  the  firms 
are  able  to  affect  the  price  by  deciding  to  produce  more  or  less. 

When,  under  such  circumstances,  several  producers  in  the  industry 
have  unused  capacity,  they  may  recognize  that  an  attempt  on  their 
part  to  increase  production  will  lower  prices  and  that  the  price 
reduction  necessary  to  take  the  larger  volume  off  the  market  may 
make  their  entire  operations  unprofitable.  Each  one  knows  that  if 
he  lowers  his  price  in  an  effort  to  get  more  business  his  competitors 
must  lower  their  prices.  They  produce  whatever  quantity  they  can 
sell  at  the  existing  price  but  they  may  or  may  not  produce  additional 
quantities  which  will  lower  the  price.  That  will  depend  upon  how 
much  the  price  must  be  lowered  to  absorb  the  increased  quantity  and 
whether  or  not  and  how  much  unit  costs  will  decline  as  production  is 
increased.  But  because  each  knows  that  increased  production  will 
lower  the  price  the  individual  producer  may  restrict  his  output  and 
leave  some  of  his  capacity  idle  without  entering  into  any  agreement 
with  his  competitors  to  affect  the  market  price. 

In  general  it  can  be  stated  that  the  more  producers  there  are  com- 
peting for  a  particular  market,  the  more  competitive  will  the  market 
price  be.  As  the  number  of  producers  increases  it  becomes  more 
difficult  for  any  one  of  them  to  influence  the  market  price  and  to 


gQ  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

take  into  account  the  effect  that  his  actions  will  have  upon  his  com- 
petitors until  a  point  is  reached  where  the  individual  producer  disre- 
gards his  own  influence  upon  price.  The  fewer  the  number  of  pro- 
ducers the  less  likely  is  it  that  any  one  of  them  will  pursue  any 
course  that  will  seriously  disturb  the  market  price.  Thus  there  are 
degrees  of  monopolistic  competition.  Some  cases  are  very  close  to 
pure  competition  in  that  any  single  producer  has  little  ability  to 
affect  the  price.  In  other  cases,  however,  the  number  of  firms  is 
so  small  and  each  one  is  so  reluctant  to  initiate  price  changes  that  the 
situation  is  very  similar  to  that  in  which  a  single  producer  controls 
the  entire  output. 

It  is  easy  to  see  that  when  competition  is  imperfect  because  of  the 
small  number  of  producers  it  can  be  profitable  to  export  at  less  than 
the  domestic  price.  A  firm  which  is  selling  all  it  can  at  the  market 
price  may  have  unused  capacity  that  it  can  utilize  in  supplying  for- 
eign markets  at  a  lower  price.  After  producing  all  it  needs  for  the 
domestic  market  it  may  be  able  to  produce  additional  output  at  the 
same  or  even  lower  costs.  To  sell  this  output  in  the  domestic  market 
would  force  down  the  price  not  only  for  the  additional  output  but 
for  the  volume  of  sales  it  is  already  making  in  the  domestic  market. 
By  selling  this  additional  output  for  a  lower  price  in  the  foreign 
market  it  does  not  disturb  the  existing  price  in  the  domestic  market. 
Under  monopolistic  competition  it  may,  therefore,  be  profitable  to 
export  at  lower  prices  because  an  attempt  to  force  that  output  on  to 
the  domestic  market  would  lower  the  domestic  price.  Under  pure 
competition,  however,  there  would  be  no  incentive  for  the  individual 
producer  to  export  at  lower  prices  because  that  output  could  be  sold 
in  the  domestic  market  without  materially  lowerinp-  the  price. 

Hence,  it  may  be  said  in  summary  that  lower  exi-<^'rt  than  domestic 
prices  cannot  be  accepted  as  prima  facie  evidence  of  monopoly  in 
the  usual  sense  of  the  term.  That  is,  if  one  defines  monopoly  as  a 
condition  where  one  producer  controls  total  production  of  a  com- 
modity or  the  several  producers  are  acting  together  to  control  pro- 
duction and  prices  then  monopoly  is  not  a  necessary  condition  for 
dumping.  It  can  take  place  under  competition.  But  two  kinds  of 
competition  must  be  distinguished;  pure  and  monopolistic  com- 
petition. Dumping  can  take  place  under  conditions  of  imperfect 
competition  as  well  as  under  monopoly.  Therefore,  the  most  that 
can  be  proven  by  the  existence  of  lower  export  than  domestic  prices 
is  that  competition  is  monopolistic  in  character.  This  does  not  mean 
that  an  actual  monopolistic  situation  may  not  exist,  but  merely 
that  lower  export  prices  alone  cannot  prove  that  it  does. 

This  theoretical  conclusion  is  completely  supported  by  the  facts 
brought  out  in  the  field  survey.  There  were  46  cases  in  which  at  least 
some  export  prices  were  lower  than  domestic  prices.  A  wide  diversity 
of  products  and  industries  are  represented  by  this  group.  Most  of 
them  are  usually  held  to  be  competitive  industries  and  have  never 
been  charged  with  monopolistic  practices  in  the  legal  sense.  What- 
ever price  policies  these  firms  have,  they  have  adopted  them  inde- 
pendently. They  represent  instances  of  monopolistic  competition 
rather  than  monopoly.  Any  one  who  scans  the  list  of  products  in- 
cluded in  these  46  cases  will  be  convinced  of  this  conclusion.  There 
are  undoubtedly  some  cases  of  monopoly  in  the  list  but  the  majority 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  gj 

are  surely  what  are  generally  conceived  of  as  competitive  industries. 

It  would  be  interesting  to  know  how  many  of  the  46  cases  in  group 
III  are  instances  of  monopoly  as  distinguished  from  monopolistic 
competition.  Of  course,  this  is  a  difficult  question  to  answer  because 
proof  of  monopolistic  practices  is  not  readily  available.  But  this 
much  can  be  said.  In  7  of  the  cases  the  holding  of  important  patents 
certainly  puts  those  firms  in  the  category  of  monopolies.  In  several 
other  cases  certain  peculiarities  of  price  behavior,  or  the  opinion  of 
specialists  in  the  industry  concerned,  or  the  confidential  admission  by 
the  firm  itself  suggests  that  the  firms  in  the  industry  are  not  acting 
with  complete  independence.  We  doubt  that  the  most  critical  person 
would  put  that  number  higher  than  8  although  our  conviction  is  not 
\ery  strong  in  more  than  6  cases.  The  rest  are  cases  of  monopolistic 
competition.  On  the  other  hand  there  appear  to  be  5  cases  among 
the  30  in  groups  I  and  II  where  monopolistic  practices  seem  likely. 

B.  The  influence  of  tariffs. — The  existence  of  tariff  protection  is 
often  considered  to  be  a  necessary  condition  for  a  continued  policy  of 
lower  export  than  domestic  prices.  This  is  not  strictly  true.  All 
that  is  necessary  is  that  the  exported  goods  be  prevented  from  reen- 
tering the  country  of  origin  and  underselling  the  domestically  offered 
goods  on  the  home  market.  A  tariff  can  be  the  means  of  blocking 
such  reentry  but  it  is  not  the  only  means.  In  most  cases  the  exporter 
has  enough  control  over  the  foreign  buyer  to  prevent  him  from  re- 
shipping  to  the  exporter's  home  market.  The  foreign  buyer  is  usually 
dependent  upon  the  exporter  for  the  continued  supply  of  the  com- 
modity which  enables  him  to  stay  in  business  and  he  would  not  jeop- 
ardize a  profitable  business  relationship  for  a  temporary  gain.  Be- 
sides this  the  transportation  costs  both  ways  would  often  be  high 
enough  in  relation  to  the  price  concession  given  to  prevent  re- 
shipment. 

The  tariff  does,  however,  play  a  significant  role  in  many  instances 
of  lower  export  prices  in  that  it  limits  the  competition  which  foreign 
firms  may  inject  into  the  domestic  market.  In  many  cases  it  was 
stated  that  lower  export  than  domestic  prices  are  necessary  in  order 
to  meet  low-priced  foreign  competition.  A  tariff  which  intentionally 
excludes  such  competition  from  the  domestic  market  thereby  creates 
the  economic  conclitions  under  which  prices  may  be  higher  in  the 
domestic  market  than  abroad.  Competition  is  less  intensive  with 
tariff  protection  (provided  that  protection  is  effective)  than  it  would 
be  in  the  same  industry  without  tariff  protection. 

Of  all  the  major  products  represented  among  the  46  cases  of  group 
III  only  one  is  on  the  free  list.  All  the  others  have  a  greater  or  lesser 
degree  of  tariff  protection  against  foreign  competition.  In  export 
markets  the  firms  must  meet  this  competition  on  an  equal  footing 
and  in  many  cases  they  must  meet  it  by  price  concessions. 

It  cannot  be  said  that  the  tariff  is  the  decisive  factor  in  all  cases 
of  lower  export  prices.  Products  which  do  not  have  protection  may 
be  exported  at  lower  prices  and  products  which  have  protection  may 
be  exported  at  identical  or  higher  prices.  Even  among  the  cases  of 
group  I  and  II  there  is  only  one  major  product  on  the  free  list.  It  is 
generally  true,  however,  that  the  products  in  these  cases  do  not  have 
as  much  foreign  competition  in  foreign  markets  as  those  in  group  III. 
Many  industries  have  tariffs  which  are  largely  meaningless  because 


g2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

there  would  be  no  significant  foreign  competition  even  if  there  were 
no  tariff.  In  these  cases  there  is  no  significant  foreign  competition 
facing  United  States  products  in  foreign  markets. 

Among  the  46  cases  of  group  III,  therefore,  there  are  some  in  which 
the  tariff  is  of  no  importance  as  a  factor  in  lower-priced  exports 
and  many  more  in  which  it  is  of  little  importance.  While  it  is 
difficult  to  assess  the  precise  role  of  the  tariff  in  every  case  or  to 
determine  what  the  price  situation  would  be  without  it,  it  is  probable 
that  the  tariff  is  a  factor  of  significant  importance  in  22  cases  out  of 
the  46  which  are  exporting  at  lower  prices.  In  those  22  cases  a 
removal  of  the  tariff  might  considerably  influence  the  domestic  price 
and  thus  bring  export  and  domestic  prices  more  clearly  into  line. 
In  the  other  24  cases  it  would  appear  that  the  condition  of  mo- 
nopolistic competition  in  the  domestic  market  would  not  be  seriously 
disturbed  by  the  removal  of  the  tariff.  Therefore,  there  would  be 
exporting  at  lower  prices  even  without  the  tariff. 

The  relation  of  the  tariff  to  our  problem  may  be  summarized  as 
follows:  International  price  discrimination  is  due  to  the  existence 
of  a  condition  of  monopolistic  competition  or  a  condition  of  mo- 
nopoly. Either  of  these  conditions  can  arise  independently  of  tariff 
protection.  In  many  cases,  however,  approximately  half  in  our  sample, 
the  protective  tariff  is  of  prime  importance  in  the  maintenance  of  a 
high  degree  of  monopolistic  competition  or  a  monopoly  position. 

C.  The  selling  prohlem  in  the  domestic  and  foreign  markets. — 
In  the  cases  of  imperfect  competition  arising  from  product  differ- 
entiation the  selling  problem  is  an  important  factor  which  often 
leads  to  higher  domestic  than  export  prices.  The  individuality  of 
one  firm's  products  which  is  developed  in  the  domestic  market  can 
not  be  developed  in  many  cases  in  foreign  markets.  The  marketing 
procedures  and  competitive  weapons  which  are  available  to  a  firm 
in  the  domestic  market  are  often  not  available  to  it  in  foreign  mar- 
kets. 

The  average  American  firm  entered  business  and  is  in  business 
today  primarily  to  produce  for  and  sell  in  the  don^estic  market.  If 
it  develops  an  export  business  it  is  usually  only  as  a'supplement  to  its 
domestic  business.  By  and  large,  it  develops  its  reputation  in  and 
designs  its  products  for  the  domestic  market. 

A  typical  firm,  let  us  say,  sells  90  percent  of  its  output  in  the  do- 
mestic market  and  10  percent  in  a  hundred  or  more  foreign  maikets. 
The  domestic  market  is  a  highly  concentrated  market  with  a  rather 
homogeneous  population.  It  has  somewhat  similar  tastes  and  it  has 
a  relatively  high  per-capita  income.  The  foreign  markets  are  spread 
to  all  parts  of  the  world;  the  populations  are  extremely  diversified 
in  language  and  modes  of  living;  standards  of  living  are  markedly 
different  and  income  is  generally  much  lower  than  in  the  United 
States. 

These  differences  give  ample  evidence  that  the  selling  problem  of 
the  export  manager  is  much  different  than  the  problem  of  the  do- 
mestic-sales manager.  Having  a  large  volume  of  sales  concentrated 
in  one  market  in  which  it  is  usually  necessary  to  maintain  a  one- 
price  policy  makes  it  imperative  that  domestic  prices  over  the  years 
cover  full  costs.  But  it  also  allows  much  greater  latitude  in  the 
methods  by  which  sales  are  obtained  and  profitable  prices  maintained. 


CXDNCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  g3 

In  selling  in  the  domestic  market  the  entire  equipment  of  salesmen 
and  advertising  can  be  effectively  used  as  competitive  weapons  in 
addition  to  price  policy.  The  export  manager  who  cannot  expect 
more  than  a  small  volume  from  any  one  of  his  many  foreign  markets 
cannot  indulge  in  these  sales  methods.  He  is  thrown  back  upon  price 
as  his  essential  competitive  weapon.  Usually  if  he  cannot  meet  com- 
petition on  a  price  basis  he  does  not  have  the  alternative  of  adver- 
tising or  organizing  a  traveling  sales  force.  He  cannot  develop  con- 
sumer preference  for  his  product,  he  cannot  create  a  reputation  for 
his  firm  or  brand,  and  he  is  therefore  forced  to  sell  on  a  price  basis. 

In  many  cases,  the  domestic-  and  export-sales  managers  have  an 
entirely  different  point  of  view  toward  competition.  Domestic  prices 
may  be  set  by  the  ranking  executives  of  the  company,  of  course,  not 
without  consideration  of  market  conditions.  The  sales  manager 
views  his  job  as  one  of  going  out  and  getting  the  business  by  ef- 
fective advertising,  effective  coverage  of  the  market,  and  by  an  ef- 
ficient sales  force.  Of  course,  he  thinks  the  price  must  be  right  but 
he  often  does  not  look  upon  price  as  the  primary  means  of  getting 
more  sales. 

The  export  manager,  however,  is  much  more  price  conscious  be- 
cause he  often  has  no  other  way  of  enlarging  his  sales  volume.  This 
was  particularly  true  in  the  type  10  cases.  After  finding  agents  or 
outlets  to  handle  the  product  he  depends  upon  quality  and  price  to 
get  the  business.  He  is  not  in  a  position  to  expect  business  through 
an  effective  selling  job. 

D.  In  all  discussions  of  the  dumping  problem  the  importance  of 
monopoly  as  a  necessary  condition  is  stressed  only  for  systematic 
dumping  over  long  periods  of  time.  It  is  recognized  that  sporadic 
dumping  can  occur  under  highly  competitive  conditions  for  a  variety 
of  reasons  such  as  to  get  a  foothold  in  new  markets,  to  dispose  of 
outdated  styles  or  models,  to  avoid  temporary  flooding  the  domestic 
market,  etc. 

"'A  long  period  of  time  '  in  economic  literature  is  a  period  in  which 
there  is  a  chance  for  long-run  equilibrium  price  to  be  established — 
in  the  absence  of  changes  which  might  alter  that  equilibrium.  That 
means  a  period  of  time  in  which  the  quantity  of  productive  resources 
available  for  the  production  of  a  particular  commodity  can  become 
adjusted  to  the  volume  of  demand. 

Now  the  evidence  of  lower  export  prices  gathered  in  the  field 
survey  of  necessity  refers  to  the  current  practices  of  business  organ- 
izations. The  evidence  does  refer  to  the  practices  in  use  for  the  past 
few  3'ears,  usually  for  most  of  the  past  decade,  and  not  to  instances 
of  a  sporadic  character.  But  it  does  not  coincide  with  conditions  of 
long-run  equilibrium  in  the  economic  meaning  of  the  term.  Many 
industries  have  been  operating  under  conditions  far  removed  from 
equilibrium  during  recent  years. 

The  existence  of  rather  serious  disequilibrium  is  of  primary  "mpor- 
tance  in  explaining  lower  export  prices  in  several  cases  in  the  sample, 
and  particularly  so  in  several  cases  of  quite  standardized  pro  ^'icts. 
In  these  industries  which  are  characterized  by  a  high  degree  of  price 
competition  in  the  domestic  market  there  are  firms  with  a  large  excess 
of  capacity.    The  excess  is  due  to  the  fact  that  demand  has  declined 

257769 — 41— No.  6 7 


^A  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

over  the  past  10  or  15  years.  The  existing  equipment  would  not  be 
required  even  with  any  feasible  reduction  in  the  domestic  price. 

Of  course,  this  represents  a  condition  of  imperfect  competition  but 
if  the  industry  was  in  approximately  an  equilibrium  position  it  is 
unlikely  that  any  firm  would  export  at  lower  than  domestic  prices. 
If  existing  equipment  was  being  utilized  to  pupplj^  the  domestic  mar- 
ket it  would  not  pay  any  firm  to  purchase  additional  equipment  to 
produce  for  foreign  markets  at  lower  prices.  In  other  words,  current 
export  prices  are  not  high  enough  to  maintain  a  continuous  supply  of 
the  product  when  the  existing  equipment  needs  replacement.  It  pays 
to  use  the  equipment  rather  than  let  it  deteriorate  by  idleness  but  it 
would  not  pay  to  install  equipment  to  produce  at  current  export  prices. 

In  a  few  cases  of  declining  industries  the  current  disequilibrium  be- 
tween productive  capacity  and  demand  is  the  most  important  factor 
in  export  price  policy.  It  is  also  a  factor  of  minor  importance  in  many 
other  cases.  Many  firms  started  their  export  business  with  prices  equal 
to  domestic  prices.  They  developed  a  certain  volume  of  export  busi- 
ness during  the  1920's  and  did  not  attempt  to  increase  that  volume  by 
adjusting  price  to  local  market  condition.  After  1929  they  found  ex- 
port sales  dwindling,  more  in  some  markets  than  in  others.  Currency 
depreciation  added  more  complications  to  the  exporter's  problem.  It 
was  often  found  necessary  to  reduce  export  prices  to  get  some  of  the 
volume  of  exports  to  which  the  business  had  been  adjusted.  While  the 
firm  would  never  have  entered  export  markets  at  lower  than  domestic 
prices,  it  found  it  better  to  stay  in  those  markets  even  at  lower  prices 
after  having  developed  facilities  for  exporting. 

^.  Other  Factors  Influencing  Export  Price  Policy. 

The  conclusion  was  stated  earlier  in  this  chapter  that  none  of  the 
cases  of  group  III  were  operating  under  conditions  of  pure  competi- 
tion. Monopolistic  competition  characterizes  the  majority  of  the  cases 
and  monopoly  in  the  usual  sense  of  the  term  probably  prevails  in  about 
one-seventh  of  the  cases.  It  will  be  readily  recognized  that  this  does 
not  differentiate  the  group  III  cases  from  those  in  groups  I  and  II  as  it 
can  hardly  be  said  that  many  cases  in  the  sample  are  operating  under 
conditions  which  even  approximate  pure  competition.  Probably  the 
nearest  thing  to  pure  competition  is  represented  by  the  four  "commod- 
ity" cases  of  type  4:  Packing-house  products;  flour-mill  products; 
canned  fruits  and  vegetables,  and  (certain)  dairy  products.  On  the 
basis  of  the  domestic  competitive  factor  alone,  therefore,  there  is  no 
reason  why  most  of  the  cases  in  groups  I  and  II  could  not  price  some 
of  their  exports  lower  to  the  advantage  of  the  company.  Hence,  it  is 
desirable  to  point  out  some  of  the  otlier  differences  between  the  groups. 
Because  of  the  limitations  of  the  sample  and  because  it  was  not  feasible 
to  obtain  a  statistical  measure  of  the  extent  of  lower  prices  exporting 
case  by  case  the  importance  of  these  factors  does  not  always  show  up  in 
a  contrast  of  the  groups.  But  their  importance  will  nevertheless  be 
evident. 

The  first  thing  to  consider  is  the  difference  between  the  types  of 
products  exported  at  higher  or  ecjual  to  domestic  prices  and  those 
exported  at  lower  prices.  The  major  products  in  each  of  the  76  cases 
are  shown  in  the  following  table: 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  g5 

Leading  products  of  firms  included  in  sample 
Group  I : 
Type  1: 

1.  Chemical  product. 

2.  Chemical  product. 
Type  2: 

3.  Wood  pulp  product. 

4.  Silk  textile  product. 

5.  Chemical  product. 
Type  3 : 

6.  Radios. 

7.  Radios. 

8.  Electric  refrigerators. 

9.  Electric  refrigerators. 
Group  II : 

Type  4 : 

10.  Packing  house  products. 

11.  Flour  mill  products. 

12.  Canned  fruits  and  vegetables. 

13.  Canned  milk. 
Type  5 : 

14.  Piece  goods. 
Type  6 : 

15.  Adding  and  calculating  machines. 

16.  Adding  machines. 

17.  Adding,  calculating,  and  bookkeeping  maehin*fe. 

18.  Laboratory  apparatus. 

19.  Scientific  equipment. 

20.  Machine  tools. 

21.  Pipe  fittings. 

22.  Phonograph  records. 

23.  Writing  paper. 

24.  Paper  grocery  specialties. 

25.  Felt  and  other  hats. 

26.  Men's  furnishings. 

27.  Women's  hosiery  and  accessories. 

28.  Hosiery,  all  kinds. 

29.  Automolbiles. 

30.  Automobiles  and  trucks. 
Group  III : 

Type  7: 

31.  Machine  tools. 

32.  Diversified  machinery  line. 

33.  Paper  and  stationery  specialties. 

34.  Control  and  measuring  instruments. 

35.  Industrial  chemicals. 

36.  Plumbing  specialties. 

37.  Cigarettes. 

38.  Abrasives. 
Type  8 : 

.39.  Profes.sioiial  supplies. 

40.  Fountain   pens. 

41.  Safety  appliances. 

42.  Sanitary  napkins  and  cleansing  tissues. 

43.  Typewriters. 

44.  Typewriters. 

45.  Abrasive  and  refractory  products. 
Type  9 : 

46.  Carbon  paper  and  ink  ribbons. 

47.  Compre.ssor.'!  and  pumps. 

48.  Professional  equipment  and  supplies. 

49.  Packaged  foods. 

50.  Stationery  supplies. 

51.  Paiiitti,   vaniislios.   etc. 


gg  OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Leading  products  of  firms  included  in  sample — Continued 

Group  III— Continued. 
Type  10: 

52.  Stationery  and  school   supplies. 

53.  Pharmaceutical  specialties. 

54.  Extensive  drug  line. 

55.  Extensive  drug  line. 

56.  Automotive  and  household  chemicals. 

57.  Industrial  lubricants  and  specialties. 

58.  f*hotographic  equipment. 

59.  Industrial  machinery. 

60.  Tools. 

61.  Linoleum  and  related  products. 

62.  .Structural  insulating  and  wall  board. 
6o.  Lime,  plaster,  and  related  products. 

64.  Reinforced  building  paper. 

65.  Electrical  machinery  and  equipment. 

66.  Carbon  products. 
Type  11: 

67.  Household  and  industrial  machines. 
Type  12: 

68.  Cotton  yarns. 

69.  Household  textiles. 

70.  Plumbing  fixtures  and  related  products. 

71.  Chenu'cal  product. 

72.  Glass  products. 

73.  Glass  products. 
Type  13: 

74.  Staple  textile  products. 

75.  Paper  products. 

76.  Merchandise. 

Among  those  exported  at  higher  or  equal  prices  one  can  distinguish 
three  classes  of  products:  (1)  Peculiarly  American  products  for 
which  there  is  as  yet  no  serious  foreign  competition,  (2)  a  few  com- 
modities which  are  widely  traded  internationally,  and  (3)  branded 
consumers'  goods. 

The  mass  production  items  of  which  American  producers  are  world 
leaders  include  such  products  as  automobiles,  electric  refrigerators, 
adding  machines,  radios,  and  full-fashioned  silk  hosiery.  While 
these  goods  are  produced  in  many  countries  foreign  producers  can 
not  compete  eifectively  with  American  products  on  a  price  basis 
where  both  products  are  on  an  equal  footing.  Of  course,  it  is  no 
doubt  possible  for  American  firms  in  these  industries  to  vary  export 
prices  to  fit  local  market  conditions  but  since  they  obtain  a  good 
export  business  without  that  complication  they  have  no  strong  in- 
ducement to  alter  their  present  price  policy.  The  point  is  well  illus- 
trated by  the  difference  between  adding  machines  and  typewriters. 
It  was  found  in  three  cases  that  producers  of  adding  machines 
export  at  domestic  prices  and  all  three  said  they  were  able  to  do  so 
because  there  was  no  effective  foreign  competition.  The  products 
of  the  three  companies  are  all  different  in  design  and  price  and  com- 
pete with  each  other  in  the  domestic  market.  They  also  compete  in 
foreign  markets  but  not  with  foreign  competition  which  they  do  not 
have  in  the  domestic  market.  The  two  typewriter  companies  inter- 
viewed, on  the  other  hand,  have  been  forced  to  make  price  conces- 
sions in  export  markets  because  of  the  competition  of  foreign 
products.  Typewriters  are  one  of  the  few  industrial  products  on  the 
free  list.     Foreign  machines  are  imported  and  sold  in  the  American 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  g7 

market.  But  while  that  competition  has  not  been  effective  in  the 
domestic  market  it  has  been  attractive  to  the  foreign  consumer. 
The  typewriter  was  developed  and  perfected  in  this  country  and  for 
years  the  American  product  had  virtually  no  foreign  competition. 
Productive  capacity  was  and  is  geared  to  a  large  volume  of  exports. 
It  is  only  natural  that  when  foreign  competition  developed  that  our 
producers  should  try  to  hold  their  share  of  the  market. 

The  staple  commodities  exported  at  domestic  prices  require  no 
special  comment.  They  are  sold  on  world  markets  at  the  market 
price  and  all  the  companies  interviewed  claimed  that  pricing  lower 
on  a  continuous  basis  would  not  be  profitable.  Several  of  them 
admitted  to  occasional  export  sales  under  the  domestic  price  when 
stocks  are  excessive  but  all  felt  that  the  processor's  margin  was  too 
small  for  extensive  use  of  this  practice. 

The  few  cases  of  branded  consumers'  goods  which  are  not  par- 
ticularly American  products  would  seem  to  represent  merely  in- 
stances of  arbitrary  export-price  policy.  There  is  no  reason  why 
those  export  prices  should  be  equal  to  domestic  prices,  except  that 
the  companies  want  to  do  business  that  way.  They  do  not  sell  in 
the  United  States  on  a  price  basis  and  they  do  not  care  to  sell  in 
foreign  markets  on  a  price  basis. 

The  products  in  group  III  which  are  exported,  to  some  extent,  at 
less  than  the  domestic  price  generally  compete  with  similar  goods 
of  foreign  manufacture.  They  are  often  outstanding  in  quality  but 
there  is  usually  a  reasonable  substitute  which  the  foreign  purchaser 
can  buy  at  a  lower  price  in  his  local  market.  Quite  often  the  price 
of  the  local  product  is  lower  because  of  the  high  tariff  paid  on 
imported  goods  or  high  freight  costs ;  nevertheless,  the  consumer  has 
the  cheaper  alternative.  As  difficult  as  it  is  to  make  generalizations 
about  these  groups  it  can  be  said  that  the  group  III  cases  are  subject 
to  much  greater  foreign  competition  than  the  other  two  groups. 

It  is  frequently  stated  that  price  competition  is  less  intense  among 
products  that  have  reached  the  stage  of  final  consumers'  goods  than 
among  products  that  are  to  be  used  in  business  presumably  because 
brand  names  are  apt  to  have  more  influence  upon  the  consumer  than 
upon  businessmen.  In  the  following  table  tlie  major  products  of  the 
cases  have  been  classified  into  consumers'  and  various  producers' 
goods.  All  building  materials  have  been  classified  as  capital  goods. 
Out  of  the  44  cases  classified  as  producers'  goods  30  are  in  group  III 
while  of  the  32  cases  of  consumers'  goods  only  16  are  in  group  III. 
That  is,  two-thirds  of  the  producers'  goods  cases  export  at  lower 
prices  while  only  one-half  of  the  consumers'  ^oods  cases  follow  that 
practice.  Since  the  practice  presumably  indicates  less  competition 
in  the  domestic  market  it  might  be  argued  that  this  evidence  shows 
less  competition  among  producers'  than  among  consumers'  goods. 
The  sample,  however,  is  hardly  large  enough  to  justify  this  conclu- 
sion although  it  does  indicate  that  the  reverse  conclusion  is  not 
self-evident. 


88 


OONCBNTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER 
Classification  of  cases  by  types  of  product 


Group  I -. 

Export  prices  higher  than  domestic 

Typel - - 

Type  2 

Type  3 

Group  II 

Export  and  domestic  prices  equal: 

Type  4 

Types... 

Type  6 - 

Group  III 

Export  prices  lower  than  domestic: 

Type? 

Types - 

Type  9 

Type  10... 

Type  11 

Type  12 

Type  13. 

Total 


Total 


46 


Final 
con- 
sumers' 
goods 


76 


32 


Branded 
final  con- 
sumers' 
goods 


27 


Pro- 
ducers' 
goods  for 
further 
process- 
ing 


15 


Pro- 
ducers' 
supplies 


Capital 
goods 


The  following  table  indicates  several  other  factors  of  importance 
in  the  determination  of  export  price  policy. 

It  is  obvious  on  the  face  of  it  that  by  lowering  export  prices  a 
company  will  increase  the  volume  of  its  export  sales.  There  is  no 
other  reason  for  adopting  that  price  policy.  It  does  not  follow  that 
among  firms  producing  diflferent  products  those  which  make  conces- 
sions on  export  prices  will  export  a  larger  share  of  their  output. 
The  table  shows  the  percent  of  sales  exported  by  the  various  types 
of  cases.  Of  the  30  cases  in  groups  I  and  II,  22  export  10  percent 
or  more  of  total  sales.  But  of  the  46  cases  in  gi'oup  III,  only  22  have 
that  large  a  percentage  of  sales  in  export  markets.  In  this  group 
13  cases  are  able  to  export  only  2  percent  or  less  despite  price  reduc- 
tions while  no  more  than  2  cases  in  the  other  groups  fall  into  that 
category. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


89 


Total 
cases 

Percent  of  sales  exported 

1  or  more 
foreign 
plants 

Export 

2  percent 
or  less 

2  percent 

to  10 
percent 

10  percent 
or  over 

from  the 
foreign 
plants 

Group  I- - 

9 

1 

8 

3 

2 

Type  1 --- 

2 

3 
4 

2 
2 
4 

T3^e2- 

1 

Types 

3 

2 

Group  II  -  .         - 

21 

2 

5 

14 

3 

3 

Type  4           .                 

4 

1 

16 

1 

1 
1 
3 

2 

1 

1 

Types 

Type  6 

1 

12 

2 

2 

Group  III 

46 

13 

11 

22 

22 

19 

Type? 

Types. 

8 
7 
6 
15 
1 
6 
3 

2 

4 
2 

1 
3 

2 

5 
3 
10 

1 
1 

2 
2 
2 
12 

1 
3 

2 
1 

Type  9     -         . 

2 
2 

2 

Type  10.- 

11 

Type  11 

1 

Type  12 

4 
'3 

1 

2 

Type  13- - 

'  Percent  exported  is  somewhat  higher  for  a  few  of  the  manufacturers  represented  by  these  exporters. 

This  is  a  definite  indication  that  those  firms  which  are  forced  to 
make  price  concessions  on  export  sales  are  exporting  less  of  their 
total  sales  than  firms  which  make  no  price  concessions.  Even  among 
the  group  III  cases  the  same  relationship  exists;  that  is  generally 
speaking,  the  more  extensive  the  concessions  the  smaller  the  per- 
centage of  sales  exported.  The  reason  for  this  is  not  difficult  to  find. 
It  is  that  the  firms  with  a  natural  export  product  do  not  have  to 
make  price  concessions  to  get  a  large  volume  of  exports.  The  pecul- 
iarly American  products  mentioned  above  are  exported  in  large 
quantities  at  the  domestic  price.  There  are,  economically  speaking, 
our  natural  export  products.  On  the  othf  hand,  those  products 
which  can  only  be  exported  at  reduced  prices  are  not  so  readily  salable 
in  export  markets.  A  small  market  is  obtained  by  price  concessions 
but  export  volume  is  not  easily  obtained  for  those  products.  As  a 
corollary  it  may  be  stated  that  the  larger  the  volume  of  exports  the 
less  able  is  the  firm  to  give  price  concessions.  A  large  volume  of  ex- 
ports must  bear  its  full  costs  and  return  a  profit  much  more  so  than 
a  small  volume. 

The  size  of  the  export  area  in  which  a  firm  is  doing  business  also 
has  an  influence  on  its  export  price  policy  and  is  often  a  determining 
influence.  As  many  of  the  products  in  groups  I  and  II  find  natural 
export  markets  in  most  countries,  this  fact  does  not  show  up  in  a 
statistical  comparison  with  group  III.  Nevertheless,  it  is  a  fact 
that  when  a  company  tries  to  sc'^  ir  many  diverse  national  markets 
it  is  more  apt  to  be  forced  into  price  adjustments  to  meet  peculiar 
local  conditions  than  if  it  restricted  its  efforts  to  a  few  markets. 
For  example,  all  the  cases  of  type  7  would  be  in  group  II  if  they  were 
willing  to  withdraw  from  the  few  markets  to  which  they  now  give 
price  concessions.  And  several  of  the  cases  in  group  II  sell  to  rela- 
tively few  markets  because  they  insist  upon  exporting  only  at  domes- 
tic prices. 


90  OONCENTEATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER 

Another  factor  which  ajffects  export  price  policy  is  foreign  branch 
plants.  In  general  the  same  forces  which  would  induce  a  firm  to  give 
export  price  concessions  would  make  it  profitable  to  establish  manu- 
facturing branches  abroad.  From  the  above  table  it  can  be  seen  that 
one-half  of  the  cases  in  group  III  have  foreign  manufacturing 
branches  as  against  less  than  one-third  in  the  other  groups. 

In  each  case,  however,  the  establishment  of  a  foreign  branch  re- 
duces the  necessity  of  exporting  below  the  domestic  price.  Several 
of  the  companies  stated  that  it  was  their  policy  to  use  domestic  price 
on  export  business  and  to  supply  lower  priced  markets  from  their 
foreign  factories.  There  is  no  doubt  that  some  of  the  cases  in  group 
II  would  not  be  able  to  maintain  export  prices  if  they  were  not 
producing  abroad  and  that  many  of  the  cases  in  group  III  would  be 
exporting  a  large  share  of  this  output  at  lower  prices  if  they  were 
not  supplying  some  markets  locally.  It  may  be  noted  that  in  24  of 
the  28  cases  with  branch  plants  abroad  those  plants  supply  exports 
for  other  markets  in  addition  to  supplying  their  local  market.  Those 
companies  which  are  not  in  a  position  to  manufacture  abroad  or  who 
cannot  economically  decentralize  their  operations  are  more  often 
forced  to  rely  upon  price  concession  to  maintain  their  export  trade 
than  firms  which  can  produce  in  several  countries. 


CHAPTER  VII 

CONCLUSIONS 

Tliis  study  Avas  directed  primarily  toward  answering  a  specific 
question :  Can  the  existence  of  higher  domestic  than  export  prices  be 
accepted  as  prima  facie  evidence  of  actions  which  are  prohibited 
under  tlie  antitrust  laws  or,  stated  more  broadly,  does  international 
price  discrimination  occur  only  under  conditions  of  monopoly  in  one 
or  more  markets?  It  will  be  recognized  that  a  comparison  of  do- 
mestic and  export  invoice  or  quoted  prices  may  be  entirely  inappro- 
priate in  answering  this  question  since  such  prices  may  merely  reflect 
the  costs  involved  in  different  terms  and  conditions  of  sale.  Net 
factory  realizations  on  domestic  and  export  sales  must  be  used  to 
determine  the  difference,  if  any,  between  prices. 

This  investigation  demonstrates  that  international  price  discrimi- 
nation is  not  a  sure  sign  of  monopoly  as  that  term  is  generally  con- 
ceived. If  one  means  by  monopoly  that  an  industry  is  composed  of 
a  single  producer  or  that  there  is  an  explicit  or  tacit  agreement  among 
the  producers  of  an  industry  controlling  price  or  production  policy, 
then  it  must  be  said  that  different  export  than  domestic  prices  is, 
not  clear  proof  of  monopoly.  Such  price  behavi-^r  can  and  un- 
doubtedly does  occur»  in  monopolistic  industries  but  it  also  often 
occurs  in  industries  or  firms  which  are  not  monopolistic  as  defined. 

In  this  study  of  76  cases,  all  of  which  sell  in  both  domestic  and 
export  markets,  it  w^as  found  that  45  cases  transacted  at  least  some 
of  their  export  sales  at  other  than  domestic  prices.  In  9  cases  of  this 
45,  export  prices  were  sometimes  higher  than  domestic  prices  but 
never  lower,  while  in  the  remaining  36  cases  export  prices  differed 
from  domestic  in  both  directions  although  lower  prices  were  much 
more  predominant.  In  only  6  cases  was  it  found  that  all  exports 
sales  were  consummated  at  less  than  the  domestic  price.  In  only  21 
cases  of  the  76  were  export  prices  always  identical  to  domestic  prices. 
Tlius  more  than  two-thirds  of  this  limited  sample  show  some  flexibil- 
ity in  export  pricing  policy. 

It  was  brought  out  in  chapter  V  that  there  were  considerable  dif- 
ferences in  pricing  methods  and  attitudes  toward  price  policy  among 
the  45  cases  which  had  some  variation  between  domestic  and  export 
prices.  These  differences  in  price  policies  cannot  be  summarized  in 
this  concluding  chapter.  It  need  only  be  emphasized,  however,  that 
a  large  majority  of  the  cases  were  not  monopolies — that  is,  instances 
of  production  being  controlled  by  one  firm  or  by  several  firms  acting 
under  an  agreement.  In  the  opinion  of  the  investigator  not  more 
than  12  out  of  the  45  could  be  so  classified. 

The  others,  to  be  sure,  are  not  instances  of  pure  price  competition 
such  as  one  finds  among  producers  of  (say)  wheat.  The  term  mo- 
nopolistic competition,  as  contrasted  to  pure  competition,  has  been 

91 


g2  OONCENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC. POWER 

used  to  describe  the  competitive  situation  in  these  cases.  The  man- 
agement in  each  of  them  does  have  some  control  over  the  prices  at 
which  the  product  is  sold — beyond  the  mere  decision  to  produce  or 
not  to  prodiice  such  as  confronts  the  wheat  farmer — but  this  element 
of  price  control  does  not  arise  either  because  the  concern  is  the  sole 
producer  of  the  commodity  or  because  it  is  acting  in  collusion  with  the 
other  producers.  The  element  of  price  control  arises  rather  from 
either  of  two  conditions  which  were  not  contemplated  by  the  anti- 
trust laws  or  included  in  the  concept  of  monopoly  around  which  the 
antitrust  laws  were  written.  These  conditions  are  (1)  the  non- 
standardized  character  of  the  product  itself  which  allows  consumer 
preference  in  the  face  of  price  differences,  and  (2)  the  fewness  of 
producers  of  a  commodity  which  gives  to  each  some  power  to  effect 
the  price  which  all  receive  and  thus  enables  each  to  see  the  profitability 
of  maintaining  a  certain  price  without  any  agreement  among  the 
group  to  do  so.  Neither  of  these  situations  can  be  called  monopoly  and 
neither  is  unlawful  under  the  antitrust  laws. 

Such  widespread  use  of  international  price  discrimination  by  in- 
dustrial concerns  as  brought  out  in  this  study  and  the  ability  to 
exercise  some  control  over  prices  that  is  implicit  in  this  situation, 
obviously  raises  a  serious  public  question.  The  economic  system  based 
upon  free  private  enterprise  has  placed  reliance,  both  in  practice  and 
in  theory,  upon  intense  price  competition  for  securing  equity  to  the 
consumer  and  the  full  utilization  of  resources  in  production.  But 
international  price  discrimi  lation  is  an  indication  that  intense  price 
competition  may  not  be  the  prevalent  industrial  norm. 

At  first  glance  it  might  seem  that  the  interest  of  government  should 
be  directed  to  the  sphere  of  export  prices  in  an  effort  to  determine 
if  public  control  of  those  prices  can  benefit  the  domestic  consumer. 
Taking  the  lack  of  intense  price  competition  in  the  domestic  market 
for  granted,  one  may  inquire  into  the  domestic  repercussions  of  grant- 
ing price  concessions  in  foreign  markets.  The  theoretical  considera- 
tion of  this  problem  shows  that  no  single  conclusion  is  possible. 
Conditions  can  be  set  forth,  and  such  conditions  undoubtedly  exist, 
under  which  the  domestic  price  would  be  lower  if  price  concessions  are 
made  in  export  markets  than  if  such  concessions  are  not  made.  Other 
conditions  can  be  set  forth,  and  these  too  undoubtedly  exist,  under 
which  export  price  concessions  would  tend  to  raise  prices  to  the  do- 
mestic consumer.  The  conclusion,  therefore,  will  vary  with  the  under- 
lying conditions  in  the  industry  concerned — conditions  regarding  the 
character  of  domestic  and  foreign  demands  and  the  effect  of  increasing 
or  decreasing  output  upon  costs.^ 

Since  domestic  prices  in  some  instances  may  be  raided  because  lower 
prices  are  set  on  foreign  sales  there  is  a  suggestion  that  the  public  pre- 
vention of  such  export  price  concessions  offers  a  possibility  of  lower- 
ing domestic  prices  in  such  cases  and  thus  benefiting  domestic  con- 

..■J  ^''ofessor  Vlner  has  summarized  two  of  the  most  interesting  situations  as  follows  : 
'For  the  special  case  where  under  a  uniform  price  policy  the  optimum  price  would  not 
permit  of  any  export  sales,  it  has  been  shown  that  resort  to  dumping  with  a  consoquejt 
increase  in  output  would  lead  to  a  higher  domestic  price  if  marginal  costs  increased  and 
to  a  lower  domestic  price  if  marginal  costs  decreased.  The  important  problem,  however, 
of  what  is  the  effect  of  dumping  on  domestic  price  when  some  export  business  could  be 
obtained  even  under  the  optimum  uniform  price  still  awaits  solution  ;  under  these  circum- 
stances it  appears  that  resort  to  dumping  always  raises  the  maximum  revenue  domestic 
price  and  increases  the  cost  ,to  the  domestic  consumer  by  more  than  the  Increase  In 
monopoly  revenue." — Jacob  Viner,  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  vol.  3,  p.  276. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  93 

sumers.  While  not  denying  the  possibility,  the  writer  is  of  the  opinion 
that,  in  a  world  where  foreign  trade  i^  left  substantially  to  individual 
initiative,  the  restriction  of  export  price  concessions  generally  would 
be  unfruitful  in  producing  favorable  results  on  the  domestic  price 
structure.  Three  arguments  may  be  offered  in  support  of  this  con- 
clusion. 

(1)  It  would  be  virtually  impossible  to  analyze  actual  demand  and 
cost  conditions  with  sufficient  accuracy  to  provide  a  guide  for  public 
policy  and,  therefore,  virtually  impossible  to  know  in  any  given  in- 
stance whether  a  lower  or  a  higher  domestic  price  would  result  from 
Government  control  of  export  prices. 

(2)  But  there  is  a  more  important  objection  to  the  general  preven- 
tion of  lower  export  prices.  After  examination  of  the  cases  included 
in  this  study  and  conversations  with  the  business  executives  involved, 
the  writer  is  convinced  that  in  most  instances  export  price  policy  is 
determined  quite  independently  of  domestic  price  policy  and  often  by 
different  individuals.  While  there  seems  to  be  a  general  recognition 
among  business  executives  of  the  effect  of  added  output  upon  costs  and 
thus  a  recognition  of  the  possibility  of  increasing  profits  by  making 
export  price  concessions,  this  reasoning  is  seldom  carried  so  far  as  to 
give  an  interrelated  domestic  and  export  price  policy.  Such  being  the 
case,  there  is  a  likelihood  that  any  general  control  of  export  prices 
would  result  in  lower  exports  and  reduced  employment  without  the 
offsetting  advantages  of  lower  prices  and  increased  production  for  the 
domestic  market. 

(3)  The  third  reason  is  that  the  economic  adjustment  which  would 
produce  lower  domestic  prices  can  only  be  assumed  to  operate  under 
conditions  of  full  employment.  The  pressure  upon  the  producer  to 
reduce  domestic  prices  if  he  should  be  forced  to  discontinue  export 
price  concessions  and  hence  lose  some  foreign  sales  comes  from  the 
unused  capacity  which  those  lost  sales  create.  However,  as  this  study 
was  made  at  a  time  when  there  was  considerable  excess  capacity  in 
industry,  little  reliance  can  be  placed  upon  the  power  of  a  small  in- 
crease in  that  excess  to  effect  profound  price  changes. 

Thus,  if  monopoly  or  monopolistic  competition  in  domestic  industry 
leads  to  price  concessions  being  made  in  export  markets,  not  much  is 
apt  to  be  gained  through  the  Government's  operating  directly  upon 
export  prices.  This  does  not  mean  that  the  existence  of  international 
price  discrimination  does  not  present  a  problem  which  demands  the 
serious  attention  of  government  and  business.  But  it  is  a  problem 
which  lies  primarily  within  the  domestic  market  rather  than  in  export 
markets.  Export  price  discrimination  is  a  clear  sign  that  some  im- 
pediment is  restricting  competition  in  the  domestic  market,  even 
though  it  is  not  an  illegal  impediment.  It  is  the  impediment  to 
domestic  competition  which  creates  the  problem  and  demands  atten- 
tion, however,  and  not  the  signs  of  the  problem  in  export  price  policy. 
It  should  be  recognized  furthermore  that  the  possible  ill  effects  of 
monopoly — in  the  way  of  obstructing  full  employment  and  the  best 
allocation  of  resources — can  flow  just  as  well  from  widespread 
monopolistic  competition. 


PART  II 

DIRECT  FOREIGN  INVESTMENTS  IN 
AMERICAN  INDUSTRY,  1937 

Prepared  by 
PAUL  D.  DICKENS 

in  the 

Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce 
DEPARTMENT  OF  COMMERCE 


95 


FOREWORD 

American  industry  was  built  up  witli  the  help  of  large  amounts  of 
foreign  capital.  The  problem  to  which  this  study  is  directed  is  the 
extent  to  which  industrial  operations  in  the  United  States  are  today 
in  the  hands  of  foreign  ownei^. 

Of  the  $7,398,000,000  of  foreign  investments  in  the  United  States 
$1,883,000,000  represent  direct  investments  involving  1,172  companies 
and  branches  located  in  the  United  States.  These  new  estimates  are 
broken  do'^n  in  the  report  by  industry  and  by  foreign  country  in- 
volved. 

This  study  does  not  attempt  to  cover  other  phases  of  the  problem 
of  international  controls  over  our  economic  activity.  The  effect  of 
foreign  competition  through  imports,  the  existence  of  working  ar- 
langements  for  dividing  the  world  market  or  of  reciprocal  agreements 
to  respect  each  other's  home  market,  and  the  possibility  of  controls 
through  patent  rights,  are  none  of  them  here  considered.  This  study 
does  show  that  the  domestic  problems  of  industrial  management  are 
not  significantly  complicated  by  foreign  controls  reaching  into  the 
American  scene  in  the  form  of  actual  operations  within  our  bounda- 
ries. 

WiLLARD  L.  Thorp. 

Washington.  D.  C. 

97 


DIRECT  FOREIGN  INVESTMENTS  IN  AMERICAN 
INDUSTRY,  1937 

INTRODUCTORY 

Cartels,  such  as  are  common  in  Europe,  are  not  a  feature  of  indus- 
trial organization  in  the  United  States.  The  antitrust  laws  have  pre- 
vented that.  However,  there  has  been  nothing  to  prevent  cartels  from 
obtaining  a  share  of  the  American  market  by  establishing  branches 
or  subsidiaries  in  this  country.  The  study,  the  results  of  which  are 
here  presented,  has  shown  that  the  foreign  cartels  as  such  have  rarely 
established  branches  or  subsidiaries  in  the  United  States.  Several  of 
the  larger  members  of  such  cartels  have  entered  this  market  by  those 
means  and  do  exert  an  influence  in  that  manner.  The  extent  of  that 
influence,  as  shown  by  the  value  and  character  of  foreign  investments 
in  this  country,  is  analjrzed  in  this  report. 

Foreign  investments  in  the  United  States  at  the  end  of  1937  aggre- 
gated $7,398,000,000,  as  shown  in  table  I.  The  short-term  investments, 
which  totaled  $1,920,000,000,  took  the  form  largely  of  deposits  in 
United  States  banks.  Direct  investments  amounted  to  $1,883,000,000 
followed  closely  in  size  by  investments  in  common  stocks  at  $1,850,- 
000,000.  Foreign  holdings  of  United  States  preferred  stocks  and 
bonds  and  other  investments  were  much  smaller. 

Deposits  of  foreign  funds  in  United  States  banks  are  extremely  vol- 
atile, flowing  freely  and  rapidly  into  and  out  of  the  country  as  Influ- 
enced by  political  and  economic  rumors  and  developments  in  this  and 
in  foreign  countries.  Investments  in  United  States  common  and  pre- 
ferred stocks  and  bonds,  particularly  the  first,  are  also  subject  to  con- 
siderable fluctuations  in  value.  These  fluctuations  arise  from  the 
volume  of  purchases  and  sales,  which  are  affected  by  political  and 
economic  conditions,  like  deposits  of  foreign  short-term  funds,  al- 
though to  a  somewhat  lesser  degree.  In  addition,  fluctuations  arise 
from  the  considerable  changes  in  the  average  market  prices  of  Ameri- 
can common  stocks  that  frequently  occur.  The  so-called  "other  in- 
vestments" are  composed  of  estates,  trust  funds,  holdings  of  real 
estate  and  real-estate  mortgages,  and  other  miscellaneous  items. 
These  are  not  highly  liquid  and  show  relatively  little  change  from 
year  to  year.    The  same  is  true  of  "direct  investments." 

Table  I. — Estimate  of  Foreign  Investments  in  the  United  States,  End  of  t037 

Type  of  investment 

Long-tprni  investments  :  Extimatct  Value 

Direct  investments   (book  value)' $1,883,000,000 

Common  stocks   (market  value)'' 1,850.000.000 

Preferred  stocks    (par  value)' 430.  00;),  OOO 

Bonds    (par   value) 565.000.000 

Other    investments 750,  000,  000 

Total    long-term 5.  478,  000.  000 

Short-term   investments 1,  920,  000,  000 

Grand   total 7, 398,  000,  000 

•  Revised. 

*  The  Finance  Division.  Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce,  is  making  an  inten- 
sive study  of  these  investments ;  the  results  of  this  study  should  be  available  during  the 
summer,  of  1940. 

257769— 41— No.  6 8  99 


FOREIGN  DIRECT  INVESTMENTS  IN  THE  UNITED 
STATES  AND  THEIR  SIGNIFICANCE 

At  the  end  of  1937  foreign  companies  and  individuals  domiciled 
abroad  controlled  a  total  of  1,172  companies  and  branches  located 
in  the  United  States.  The  total  investment  interest  of  the  foreign 
ownei*s  of  these  companies  and  branches  amounted  to  $1,882,603,000, 

Foreign  direct  investments  in  the  United  States  are  all  foreign 
investments  in  those  United  States  corporations  or  enterprises  which 
are  controlled  by  persons  or  small  groups  of  persons  (corporate  or 
natural)  domiciled  in  foreign  countries,  or  in  the  management  of 
which  such  persons  or  groups  have  an  important  voice.^  It  is  through 
this  type  of  investment  that  foreigners  most  directly  influence  pro- 
duction and  distribution  in  the  United  States  and  for  that  reason 
it  is  this  type  of  foreign  investment  that  is  discussed  here  in  detail. 

The^se  investments  had  no  common  cause,  unless  it  was  a  desire 
to  participate  more  fully  in  the  great  American  market.  Some  date 
their  beginning  before  the  Civil  War  while  others  were  only  re- 
cently started.  Some  have  grown  to  considerable  size,  as  any  pros- 
perous well -managed  business  may,  while  others  are  the  result  of 
the  merger  of  several  units,  some  of  which  may  have  been  domes- 
tically owned.  Many  of  the  maimfacturing  enterprises  are  based 
even  now  on  patent  control.  Frequently  patent  controls  were  im- 
portant in  tlie  beginning  of  the  enterprise  but  now  the  reputation 
for  a  good  product  and  good  service  is  more  vital  to  it.  The  United 
States  tariff  was  undoubtedly  a  factor  in  causing  some  factories 
t<^  be  established  to  manufacture  products  in  this  country  that  could 
not  be  imported  and  meet  the  competition  of  domestically  produced 
goods.  Other  factors,  such  as  the  costs  of  transportation,  or  the 
availability  of  a  raw  material,  were  influential  in  individual  cases. 

Tarle  II. — Forciffn  direct  invcstincnts  hi  the  United  States,  hi/  hidtistriefi,  lOM 

[In  thousuiuls  of  clolljii-s] 


Industry  Investment 
Manufacturing : 

Automobile  parts $34,821 

Iron  and  steel 6,348 

Nonferrous  metals 24,  200 

Transportation    e  q  u  i  d- 

mont 1,  790 

Machinery 31,977 

Heating    and    electrical 

equipment 11,963 

Hardware 12,276 


Induntrn  In  •'r'<t  mm  t 
Manufacturing — (Continued. 
IJuilding  and  constructed 

material   .$1"),  827 

Paper    and    wood    prod- 
ucts    18,  23^i 

r''iemicals 220,304 

Rubber 2,  ,%1 

Leather 2,  725 

Textiles 217,164 

Foodstuffs . 31,  9:W 


'  'I'hp  basis  of  tlie  classification  of  an  investment  as  '•diioot"  has  liecn  tiio  ownership  of 
thf?  common  stocK  of  tlie  enterprise.  No  arliitrary  jMTcenfaKe  of  owncrsliip  of  tin*  common 
stock  has  been  adopted  hecavisf'  a  eoiicentrated  lii.ldiiifr  of  .'iO  percent  of  tin  stock  may  give 
control  of  i)olicies  us  effectively  as  a  mor(>  widely  distributed  holdinK   of  50  or  00  percent. 

100 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER  101 

Tablk  II. — Foreign  direct  investments  in  the  T'uited  States,  by  Industries,  1937 — 

Continued 


Industry  Investment 

Manufacturing — Continued. 

Beverages   $65,275 

Tobacco 18,  764 

Other  manufactures 12,  500 


Total,  manufacturing—  728,  669 

Distribution 119, 161 

Transportation 257,  002 

Public  utilities 9, 182 

Petroleum 283,  450 

Mining 23,902 


Industry  Investment 

Finance : 

Banking,  i  n  v  e  s  tments, 

etc $61, 103 

Insurance 351,262 


Total,  finance 412,365 

Agriculture 12,  670 

Miscellaneous 36,  202 


Grand  total 1,882,603 


INDUSTRIAL  DISTKIBUTION 

Foreign  direct  investments  in  United  States  enterprises  in  1937 
were  distributed  over  the  whole  range  of  business  activity  in  this 
country.  ("See  table  II.)  Every  major  industry  was  represented 
from  manufacturing  to  agriculture  and  from  retail  distribution  to 
railroad  systems.  The  distribution  by  industries  was  not  even,  how- 
ever, nor  did  it  conform  to  the  relative  importance  of  the  various 
industries  in  the  United  States.  Controlling  investments  in  United 
States  public  utility  enterprises,  for  example,  were  the  smallest  in 
any  group.  Undoubtedly  one  reason  for  this  was  the  fact  that  the 
period  of  greatest  development  in  the  public  utility  field  occurred 
after  the  United  States  became  a  lender  rather  than  a  borrower.  An- 
other reason,  however,  was  the  attainment  by  electric  and  gas  utilities 
in  this  country  of  a  position  of  financial  strength  and  technical 
efficiency  before  they  did  in  foreign  countries. 

Manufacturing,  with  its  wide  range  of  nonstandnrdized  highly  com- 
petitive products,  was  the  field  of  investment  in  1987  of  $729,000,000, 
or  approximately  40  percent  of  the  total  foreign  direct  investments 
in  the  United  States.  Although  the  range  of  product  is  extremely 
wide,  in  some  branches  entrepreneurs  in  this  country  developed  ad- 
vanced techniques  and  superior  products  earlier  than  foreign  com- 
panies and  the  conditions  have  not  been  favorable  for  investments  by 
the  latter.  Other  branches  of  manufacturing  revealed  the  existence 
of  competitive  conditions  which  induced  foreign  investments.  Under 
this  latter  head  mention  needs  to  })e  made  ])articulai'ly  of  chemical, 
textile,  and  beverage  manufacturing.  Among  the  bi'anches  of  mami- 
facturing  that  were  atfocted  least  l)v  the  entrsmce  of  foreign  affiliates 
into  this  market  were  iron  and  steel.  transj)oitat  ion  i'(|nipnient,  and 
rubber. 

Just  before  the  United  States  eiiteied  the  World  War.  the  domestic 
chemical  industi'v  was  dominated  by  a  few  large  Geinian  concerns. 
The  Seizure  of  the  United  States  assets  and  patents  of  those  con- 
cerns, and  their  sale  to  domestic  intei-ests,  served  to  break'  that  dom- 
ination. This  is  an  industry,  however,  in  which  patents  play  a  ])rom- 
inent  role.  As  a  result  foi'eign  investments  in  the  cheinical  indnstry. 
including  toilet  goods  and  cosmetics,  amounted  to  $22().(K)0,()00  at  the 
end  of  1937.  As  large  as  this  investment  seems,  it  was  oidy  about  5 
or  6  percent  of  the  total  capital  invested  in  the  United  States  chem- 


102  OONCENTBATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

ical  industry.'^  Furthermore,  the  geographic  distribution  of  that  for- 
eign investment  was  much  wider  in  1937  than  in  1914,  with  England, 
France,  Netherlands,  and  Switzerland,  as  well  as  Germany,  in  im- 
portant roles. 

Textile  manufacturing  presented  yet  another  picture.  Cotton, 
wool,  and  silk  textile  production  have  not  for  years,  if  ever,  been 
dominated  by  foreign  capital.  There  were,  nevertheless,  several  old 
companies  of  more  than  average  size  that  were  controlled  abroad, 
particularly  in  England  and  France.  Rayon  manufacturing  con- 
cerns, on  the  other  hand,  were  largely  foreign  in  their  origin  and 
control,  and  in  1937  several  of  the  largest  companies  were  wholly  or 
partially  owned  by  British,  Dutch,  and  German  companies.  The 
textile  group  as  a  whole,  in  which  $217,000,000  of  foreign  capital  was 
invested,  showed  about  the  same  degree  of  foreign  control  as  did  the 
chemical  industry. 

Approximately  6  percent  of  the  capital  invested  in  the  manufactur- 
ing of  beverages  (alcoholic  and  nonalcoholic)  was  owned  abroad  in 
1937.  Foreign  ownership,  however,  was  confined  largely  to  the  manu- 
facture of  alcoholic  beverages  and  in  that  branch  comprised  a  much 
larger  part  of  the  total  investments.  The  latter  was,  of  course,  a 
development  of  the  years  after  1933.  Almost  all  of  the  $65,000,000 
of  foreign  investments  in  United  States  beer  and  whisky  manufac- 
turing companies  were  held  by  a  few  large  Canadian  companies. 

The  investment  in  financial  institutions  was  next  in  size  to  the 
manufacturing  industry,  although  only  about  60  percent  as  large.  Of 
the  $412,000,000  of  foreign  capital  invested  in  this  type  of  enterprise, 
the  net  worth  ^  of  134  foreign-owned  insurance  branches  and  sub- 
sidiaries amounted  to  $351,000,000.  Seventy  percent  of  the  net  worth 
of  these  insurance  investments  was  in  fire  and  marine  insurance 
branches  and  companies  and  only  4  percent  in  life  insurance  com- 
panies although  the  admitted  assets  of  life  insurance  companies  were 
nearly  as  large  as  those  of  the  fire  and  marine  companies.  The  dif- 
ference was  the  result  of  the  varying  statutory  reserve  requirements 
applying  to  these  types  of  companies.*  Three-fourths  of  the  direct 
investments  by  foreign  insurance  companies  were  British.  (See  table 
II.)  No  other  country  comprised  as  much  as  10  percent  of  the  total. 
Direct  investments  in  banks,  trust  companies,  and  investment  com- 
panies amounted  to  $61,000,000. 

Foreign  direct  investments  in  the  petroleum  industry,  which 
amounted  in  1937  to  $283,000,000,  covered  the  entire  range  of  produc- 
tion, pipe-line  transportation,  refining,  and  distribution.  Some  of 
these  investments  had  their  origin  before  1914.  Their  principal  ex- 
pansion, following  the  trend  of  the  industry  took  place  after  the 
close  of  the  war.  England,  Canada,  and  Netherlands  all  figured 
prominently  in  the  total.  | 

"Based  roughly  on  the  total  assets  of  chemical  companies  as  reported  in  Bureau  of 
Internal  Revenue,  Press  Service  No.  lfl-13,  showing  the  assets  and  liabilities  as  of 
December  31,  1937,  of  corporations  submitting;  balance  sheets. 

'  The  net  worth  of  these  branches  and  affiliates  of  foreign  companies,  rather  than  the 
total  admitted  assets  or  total  investments,  has  been  adopted  as  the  correct  method  of  valu- 
ing insurance  investments  because  a  large  part  of  the  assets  of  insurance  companies  are 
required  by  law  to  be  deposited  against  policy  liabilities  with  State  insurance  commis- 
sioners as  statutory  reserves. 

*  For  more  detailed  data  regarding  foreign  insurance  investments  In  the  United  States 
see  the  following  publications  of  U.  S.  Department  of  Commerce :  Trade  Information 
Bulletin  No.  8.'{4,  Insurance  Transactions  in  the  Balance  of  International  Payments  of 
the  United  States,  1919-35,  by  Dr.  August  Maffry,  published  in  1936  :  The  Balance  of 
Inrernatlonal  Payments  of  the  United  States  (published  annually),  and  Foreign  Invest- 
ments In  the  United  States,  pp.  38  and  43.  published  in  1937. 


OONCBNTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


103 


With  one  exception  the  controlling  foreign  investments  in  United 
States  railways  were  held  by  the  two  large  Canadian  systems.  These 
holdings  were  acquired  for  the  most  part  during  the  last  half  of  the 
last  century  when  the  Canadian  companies  were  seeking  direct  access 
to  Chicago  and  to  the  eastern  seaboard  of  the  United  States. 
Foreign  direct  investments  in  transportation  enterprises  in  1937 
were  estimated  at  $257,000,000. 

Direct  investments  by  foreigners  in  United  States  mining  and 
agricultural  companies  were,  up  until  about  1910,  more  numerous 
and  valuable  than  at  present.  This  was  particularly  true  of  agri- 
culture." During  the  1870-80's  British  capitalists  obtained  large 
tracts  of  land  in  the  South  and  Middle  West  either  for  exploitation 
or  as  speculations.  The  liquidation  of  such  holdings  was  very  rapid 
after  about  1900  and  during  the  World  War,  and  as  a  result  were 
relatively  unimportant  in  1937.  Controlling  investments  in  United 
States  mining  enterprises  in  1937  were  generallj^  of  rather  recent 
origin.  The  pre-war  foreign  holdings  were  usually  sold  gradually 
to  United  States  investors  so  that  while  foreigners  still  have  large 
investments  in  mining  enterprises  in  this  country  they  are  no  longer 
controlling  interests.  The  development  of  American  potash  re- 
sources, which  is  of  fairly  recent  date,  has  been  financed  largely  by 
foreign  capital  and  accounts  for  a  substantial  portion  of  the  $24,- 
000,000  invested  in  mining  enterprises. 

Import-export  houses,  and  distributors  of  foreign  specialty  articles, 
such  as  some  Japanese  and  Philippine  goods,  comprise  the  bulk  of 
the  foreign  direct  investments  in  the  distribution  industry. 


Table  III. 


-Foreign  direct  investments  in  United  States,  by  principal  countries 
and  industries,  1937 


[In  thousands  of  dollars] 

Manu- 
factur- 
ing 

Distri- 
bution 

Trans- 
porta- 
tion 

Public 
Utili- 
ties 

Petro- 
leum 

Min- 
ing 

Fi- 
nance 

Miscel- 
lane- 
ous 

Total 

Europe: 

United  Kingdom 

Netherlands 

366,547 
27,825 
65, 662 
45, 805 
24, 175 
24,109 
24,998 
11,937 

29.674 
5,009 
3,573 
6,279 

12,864 
7,411 
1,433 
3,446 

30,285 
1,032 

142 
2,467 

172 
1,490 

736 
2,801 

925 

92,940 
142, 551 

13,146 
325 
112 

277, 074 

1,266 

1,071 

147 

28,045 

11,629 

2,569 

13, 077 

22,  752 

511 

630 

249 

6,400 

1,786 

""7,'895" 

833,343 
178,  519 
71  190 

Belgium 

Qermanv    

38 
2,276 
10, 078 

54  985 

8wit7j»rlftn(1     , 

73, 932 

France 

56,  503 

Sweden 

29,736 

other  Europe  .  . 

39, 156 

Total 

591, 058 

69,689 

39,125 

925 

247.883 

13,583 

334,  875 

40,223 

1, 337, 364 

Canada ' 

130, 873 
2,205 

11,008 
13, 975 

215,  624 
6 

8,057 
200 

34,987 
149 

10, 199 
55 

45,  742 
1,516 

6,205 
292 

462.  693 

Latin  America 

18, 397 

Africa,  Asia,  and  Oceania: 
Japan. _ 

927 
1,869 

16,  531 
7,936 

1,757 
44 

21, 805 
8,386 

10 
1,085 

41,030 

other    . 

19,320 

Total 

2,796 

24,467 

1,801 

30, 191 

1,095 

60,350 

Unknown 

1,737 

22 

447 

431 

65 

33 

1,057 

3,797 

Grand  total 

728,669 

119,161   I257.n02 

0,182 

283,460 

23,902 

412, 365 

48,872 

1,882,603 

'  Including  $102,000  for  Newfoundland  ($2,000  in  mining  and  $100,000  in  "miscellaneous"). 


•  There  are  undoubtedly  some  large  unincorporated  farms  r'mi  urban  properties  owned 
by  foreigners  today  that  are  not  included  in  the  1937  estimates. 


JQ4  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

GEOGRAPHIC  DISTRIBUTION 

Seventy  percent,  or  over  $1,300,000,000,  of  the  foreign  direct  invest- 
ments in  the  United  States  in  1937  belonged  to  the  United  Kingdom 
and  the  British  Dominions.  The  bulk  of  these  large  investments — 
$833,000,000 — was  made  by  corporations  and  individuals  in  the 
United  Kingdom.  Canada  with  $463,000,000  made  up  most  of  the 
remainder.  Manufacturing  and  insurance  were  the  two  industrial 
L'^roups  in  which  British  investments  were  largely  centered.  To  an 
important  degree  both  had  a  long  history,  some  of  the  latter  going  as 
far  back  as  1804  and  the  former  to  1853.  In  many  cases  the  only 
exphmation  of  their  continued  existence  as  foreign-controlled  enter- 
))rises  was  this  historical  factor  and  their  profitability.  In  other 
cases  important  English  investments  arose  out  of  patent  controls, 
tariff  measures,  and  the  demands  of  competitive  marketing. 

Canadian  direct  investments  in  the  United  States  covered  a  wide 
range  of  activities.  They  seem  to  have  been  the  result  of  nearness 
and  the  similarity  of  markets  and  methods.  Nearness  or  contiguity 
were,  of  course,  the  determining  factor  in  the  investments  in  branch 
railway  lines  in  this  country.  To  a  very  real  degree  nearness  can 
also  be  said  to  be  a  factor  in  the  manufacturing  investments,  the 
next  most  important  group,  as  is  evident  from  the  notable  extent  to 
which  these  enterprises  are  concentrated  in  Buffalo  and  northern 
New  York.  Furthermore,  the  close  relations  that  exist  between 
Canadian  and  United  States  businessmen  naturally  lead  to  their  asso- 
ciation in  various  enterprises  or  industries. 

European  countries,  other  than  the  United  Kingdom,  likewise  had 
large  direct  investments  in  the  United  States  in  1937.  Netherlands, 
with  $178,000,000,  followed  Canada  in  size.  Switzerland,  Belgium, 
France,  and  Germany  were  next  in  that  order  of  importance.  While 
j)etr()l(Mnn  comprised  the  bulk  of  the  investment  of  the  Netherlands, 
manul'av'turing  was  a  large  part  of  the  total  of  each  of  the  countries 
listed  above.  (See  table  III.)  Chemical,  textile,  and  mechanical 
})ranclies  of  manufacturing  were  most  prominently  represented. 

Direct  investments  by  other  foreign  countries  were  scattered  and 
relatively  unim])ortant  with  the  exception  of  the  Japanese  interests. 
The,  latter  totaled  $41,000,000,  in  which  insurance  and  distribution 
enterpi-ises  wei'e  the  only  ones  of  significance. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


105 


Tabi^  IV. — Foreign  direct  investments  in  the  United  States,  by  countries,  1937 


Country 

Europe: 

Austria 

Belgium - 

C  zechoslovakia _ 

Denmark... 

France 

Germany 

Oreece 

rrish  Free  State 

Italy _ 

Lich  tenstein. 

Lithuania 

Luxembourg 

Madeira 

Monaco       

Netherlands 

Norway _.. 

Poland.. 

Portugal 

Spain 

Sweden 

Switzerland  

Union  of  Soviet  Socialist  Republics. 
United  Ki  ngdom 


I  In  thousands  of  dollars] 


Total 

investment 

155 

71, 190 

1,467 

8,138 

56,  503 

54, 985 

765 

1,107 

12,  476 

8,  257 

35 

2,757 

147 

67 

178,519 

2,318 

26 

2 

1,419 

29,  736 

73, 932 

20 

833,  343 


Total,  Europe 1,337,364 


North  America: 

Canada 4S2,593 

Newfoundland 102 


Total,  North  America. 


Mexico  and  Central  America: 

M  e.xi  CO  - 

E!  Salvador. 

Guatemala 

Honduras 

Panama... 


Total,  Mexico  and  Central  America. 


Country 


South  America-. 

Argentina...  

Total 
investment 
987 

Bolivia 

14 

Brazil... 

1,674 

Chile 

..     ..          7,777 

Peru     . . 

21 

Total,  South  America ... 

West  Indies: 

British  West  Indies 

10,47:} 
914 

Cuba 

4,980 

Dominican  Republic. 

Total,  West  Indies 

76 

5,97.'i 

Africa: 

Britisli  Africa  - 

255 

Egypt 

Total,  Africa 

3 

258 

Asia: 

British  India 

I,  260 

China 

nong  Kong 

4,803 

436 

Iraq 

106 

Japan                     * .  . 

41,030 

Netherlands  East  Indies  

Palestine 

1 

44 

Philippine  Islands 

Turkey    .                     .      •    . 

9,803 

..      .                    4 

Total,  Asia _ 

57, 487 

Oceania: 
Australia 

741 

New  Zealand.    ..    

1,864 

Total,  Oceania.. 

.    .               2,605 
3,797 

Grand  total 

....     .    1.SS2. 603 

FOREIGN  CONTROL  OF  UNITED  STATES  PRODUCTION 

The  control  over  United  States  production  exercised  by  foreign  cor- 
porations through  their  direct  investments  in  this  country  was,  on  the 
whole,  negligible  in  1937.  In  agriculture,  for  example,  while  foreign- 
ers controlled  one  of  the  largest  cotton-plantation  enterprises  in  the 
United  States  its  production  was  a  small  fraction  of  total  cotton  pro- 
duction of  this  country.  While  foreigners  owned  several  ranches  and 
one  of  them  was  between  800,000  and  900,000  acres  in  size,  with  about 
50,000  head  of  cattle,  that  too  was  only  a  fraction  of  1  percent  of  the 
total  acreage  and  stock  of  cattle.  Foreign  ownership  of  United  States 
coal,  iron,  copper,  and  timber  resources,  to  mention  a  few  important 
raw  materials,  were  insignificant. 

In  a  few  instances  a  larger  proportion  of  the  United  States  produc- 
tion of  raw  materials  was  controlled  by  foreign  corporations.  Accord- 
ing to  data  supplied  to  the  Department  of  Commerce  by  the  Bureau  of 
Mines,  foreign-controlled  oil  corporations  in  the  United  States  pro- 
duced in  1937  about  5.0  percent  of  tlie  total  crude-oil  production  in  this 
country.  The  aggregate  crude  runs  of  tlie  same  corporations  was  about 
6.9  percent  of  the  total  crude  runs.  As  of  January  1,  1938,  the  crude- 
oil  refiner}'  capacity  (operating)  of  the  foreign-owned  United  States 


106 


OONCENTRATION  OF  EXX)NOMIC  POWER 


corporations  was  about  6.4  percent  of  the  refinery  capacity  of  the 
United  States.^ 

Certain  other  branches  of  the  mineral  industry  revealed  a  larger 
concentration  of  foreign  control.  In  1937  the  only  smelter  of  antimony 
metal  in  the  United  States  was  owned  abroad.  This  company  pro- 
duced little  or  no  ore  but  obtained  a  substantial  part  of  its  antimony- 
ore  requirements  from  aflBliated  mines  in  Mexico.  The  antimony-oxide 
output  of  this  smelter  in  1937  was  roughly  25  percent  of  the  domestic 
total.  In  1938  a  new  antimony  smelter  was  put  in  operation  in  Cali- 
fornia.'^ Almost  three-fourths  of  all  of  the  potash  produced  in  the 
United  States  in  1937  was  produced  by  corporations  in  which  foreign- 
ers had  substantial  interests.  The  first  real  beginning  of  the  potash 
industry  in  this  country  was  made  after  the  outbreak  of  the  World  War 
in  1914  which  prevented  imports  from  the  former  German  sources. 
The  most  substantial  advances  were  made  after  1926  and  at  the  present 
time  over  half  of  the  United  States  consumption  is  produced  here.® 
Only  a  very  small  part  of  the  production  of  phosphate,  another  great 
fertilizer  material,  was  in  the  hands  of  foreign-owned  companies. 
More  than  90  percent  of  the  domestic  output  of  boron  minerals,  from 
which  commercial  borax  and  boric  acid  are  produced,  was  accounted 
for  by  companies  under  foreign  control. 

Table  V. — Study  of  international  affiliations  of  American  industry  based  on 
Census  of  Manufactures,  1937 


Value  of  products 

Number  of— 

Ipdustry 

United 
States 

Selected 
companies 

Percent  of 

United 

States 

total 

Establishments 

Concerns, 
selected 

United 
States 

Selected 

Paper 

$957, 939,  764 
345, 918.  343 
638,  460, 629 

788, 927, 440 

278,638,830 

113,102,963 
537, 105,  238 
144,  455,  224 

932, 749, 910 
254, 697,  216 

964, 150, 996 
652, 751, 157 

$16,  790,  895 
6, 997, 061 
2,515,886 

\    23,  790,  =02 

I  108,686,299 

}  221,444,829 
}     27,365,167 

1.8 
2.0 

.5 

2.2 

13.7 

18.6 
1.7 

647 
1,013 
1,124 

1      2, 772 

1      1, 049 

(          151 
\          653 
(          210 

f          601 
I            33 

/      2,298 
I      2, 957 

8 
11 

7 

7 

10 

12 
11 
12 

52 
10 

10 
5 

8 

Drugs  and  medicines 

11 

Paints,  pigments,  and  varnishes. 

Canned  and  dried  fruits  and 
vegetables;  canned  and  bot- 
tled juices;  preserves,  jellies, 
fruit    butters,    pickles,    and 
sauces 

Food    preparations    noi,    else- 
where classified.. 

4 

6 
4 

Liquors: 

Distilled.. 

4 

Malt  .      

9 

Rectified  or  blended 

Chemicals,  not  elsewhere  classi- 
fied  

4 
20 

Rayon  and  allied  products 

Machinery  not  elsewhere  classi- 
fied  

5 
9 

Machine-shop  products  .    ..    . 

4 

Source:  Department  of  Commerce,  Bureau  of  the  Census. 

Note  by  Finance  Division,  Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce.  The  list  of  foreign-controlled 
companies,  the  "Selected  companias,""  was  supplied  to  the  Bureau  of  the  Census  by  the  Finance  Division. 
The "Numberof  establishments"  refers  to  the  number  of  plants  in  operation  during  1937  and  the  number  of 
"Concerns'"  refers  to  the  United  States  companies  owning  the  plants. 

On  the  whole  foreign-controlled  United  States  companies  accounted 
for  only  a  very  small  part  of  the  total  output  of  manufacturing 
enterprises  in  this  country  in  1937.  In  this  industrial  group,  how- 
ever, as  in  tlie  raw-material  industries,  there  was  a  significant  con- 

'  Based  oa  data  in  Department  of  Interior,  Bureau  of  Mines,  Information  Circular  7034, 
and  in  the  files  of  the  Finance  Division,  Department  of  Commerce. 

'  Bureau  of  Mines,  Minerals  Yearbook,  1937,  p.  733,  and  1939,  p.  720. 

*  The  Annalist,  "Potash,  a  New  Industry  Making  Satisfactory  Progress,"  by  Paul  Port- 
zelt,  July  6,  1939,  pp.  4  and  7. 


CJONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER  107 

centration  of  forei^  control  over  certain  commodities.  In  order 
to  obtain  a  more  accurate  idea  of  the  volume  of  production  and  the 
percentage  controlled  by  foreigners,  the  Bureau  of  the  Census  was 
requested  to  compile  the  pertinent  data  on  the  basis  of  a  list  of 
foreign  direct  investments  in  the  United  States  which  was  supplied 
by  the  Finance  Division,  Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce. 
Those  data,  as  compiled  by  the  Bureau  of  the  Census,  are  given  in 
table  V. 

There  were  several  fairly  important  industry  groups  not  covered  by 
table  V  because  in  those  gi^oups  there  were  less  than  four  concerns  in 
the  list  of  foreign -owned  companies  or  the  production  of  one  con- 
cern in  the  group  comprised  such  a  large  part  of  the  total  for  the 
"selected  companies"  that,  in  effect,  that  total  revealed  the  approxi- 
mate production  of  the  one  large  concern.  Some  of  the  industrial 
groups  excluded  from  the  table  on  those  grounds  were  cotton  yarn 
and  thread,  woolen  yarns,  soap,  perfumes,  cosmetics,  and  other  toilet 
preparations,  rubber  tires  and  inner  tubes,  glass,  and  tobacco  and 
snuff. 

The  chief  concentrations  of  foreign-j3ontrolled  manufacturing  pro- 
duction proved  to  be  in  two  combinations  of  industries,  shown  in 
table  V;  first,  liquors — distilled,  malt,  and  rectified  or  blended;  and, 
second,  chemicals,  not  elsewhere  classified,  and  rayon  and  allied  prod- 
ucts. All  of  the  other  groups  in  table  V  showed  the  production  of 
the  "selected  companies"  to  be  2.2  percent  or  less  of  the  total  produc- 
tion. The  two  industry  combinations 'mentioned  above  were  neces- 
sitated by  the  small  number  of  companies  in  the  industries  combined 
or  by  a  concentration  of  production  in  one  concern  in  the  industry. 

It  is  quite  generally  known  that  the  United  States  production  of 
rayon,  distilled  liquors,  and  dyestuffs  in  1937  was  centered  in  forciirn- 
controlled  companies  to  a  greater  degree  than  the  percentages  in 
table  V  indicate.  Accordingly  it  was  desirable  to  ascertain,  from 
other  sources,  the  information  desired. 

In  1929  in  an  article  on  World  Investments  in  Rayon  published 
by  the  Manchester  Guardian^  (England)  the  statement  was  made 
that  foreign  capital  invested  in  five  United  States  rayon  companies 
amounted  to  £35,000,000  or  55  percent  of  the  capital  invested  in  the 
rayon  industry  in  the  United  States.  The  same  comparison  cannot 
be  made  for  a  more  recent  date  but  data  regarding  the  installed  capa- 
city of  the  rayon  plants  in  this  country  "  shows  that  between  55  and 
60  percent  of  that  capacity  was,  as  of  the  end  of  1938,  owned  by 
foreign -controlled  companies.  While  the  percentage  has  remained 
about  the  same  or  slightly  increased,  it  is  true  that  United  States 
capital  is  associated  "with  the  foreign  capital  in  those  companies  to  a 
larger  extent  than  in  1929. 

The  production  of  dyestuffs,  which  in  1914  was  almost  exclusively 
under  the  control  of  foreign  corporations,  was,  on  the  basis  of  sales 
data  compiled  by  the  United  States  Tariff  Commission,  controlled  to 
the  extent  of  only  about  30  percent  in  1938. 

The  repeal  of  the  prohibition  amendment  in  1933  presented  an  op- 
portunity to  foreign  whisky  producers  to  obtain  an  important  posi- 
tion in  this  market.  Partly  because  of  the  import  duty  of  $5  per 
proof  gallon,  those  foreign  corporations,  particularly  Canadian,  or- 

»The  Commercial,  published  by  the  Manchester  Guardian,  July  11,  1929,  p.  11. 
"  Rayon  and  Staple  Fiber  Yearbook,  third  edition,  1939,  pp.  752-771. 


IQg  OUNCENTKATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

^anized  subsidiaries  and  built  large  plants  in  this  country.  One  of 
those  plants  is  the  largest  distillery  in  the  United  States  with  a  capa- 
city of  100,000  gallons  a  day."  Two  of  the  foreign-owned  corpora- 
tions, with  the  affiliated  companies,  are  among  the  first  four  largest 
companies  distilling  and  distributing  whiskies  and  other  alcoholic 
beverages  in  the  United  States,  According  to  data  supplied  by  the 
Federal  Alcohol  Administration,  the  production  of  all  foreign- 
controlled  companies  was  between  35  and  40  percent  of  the  total 
whisky  production  of  the  United  States. 

The  impact  of  foreign  control  on  United  States  production  cannot 
be  measured  on  a  purely  quantitative  basis.  Occasionally  one  of 
these  companies  is  one  of  two  or  three  makers  in  the  United  States 
of  some  specialized  product  which  has  an  important  place  in  some 
complicated  machine  or  process.  It,  therefore,  acquires  a  significance 
far  surpassing  the  value  of  the  part  when  compared  with  the  value 
of  the  finished  machine.  Some  of  these  foreign-controlled  enterprises 
manufacture  articles  that  are  particularly  desired  by  immigi-ants 
from  a  foreign  country  or  area.  The  significance  of  the  latter  enter- 
prises is  more  sentimental  than  practical. 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ASSETS  AND  INVESTMENT 

A  special  analysis  was  made  of  data  relating  to  651  foreign-con- 
trolled United  States  companies,  excluding  insurance  companies,  in 
order  to  determine  the  technical  investment  and  financial  character- 
istics. The  foreign  investment  in  these  companies  amounted  to  $1,347,- 
000,000,  or  88  percent  of  the  total  foreign  direct  investments  in  the 
United  States,  excluding  the  investments  in  insurance  companies. 
These  651  companies  had  total  assets,  at  the  end  of  1937,  of  $2,586,- 
000,000.  Among  these,  37  concerns,  or  5.6  percent,  had  assets  in  excess 
of  $10,000,000^heir  total  assets  comprising  about  64  percent  of  the 
assets  of  the  entire  group. ^^ 

This  degree  of  concentration  followed  quite  closely  the  pattern  of 
United  States  industry  in  general.  The  manufacturing,  transporta- 
tion, petroleum,  finance,  and  trading  industries  were  represented  in 
the  group  of  larger  companies.  At  least  one  was  the  result  of  a 
merger  near  the  turn  of  the  last  century,  others  resulted  from  the 
rapid  growth  of  industries,  such  as  the  production  of  rayon  yarn, 
where  patent  control  was  important,  while  still  others  had  grown  to 
unusual  size  just  as  other  domestic  units  in  the  same  industry  had 
during  the  same  period. 

The  total  capitalization  of  the  651  companies  amounted  to  $1,911,- 
000,000,  and  the  total  common  stock  to  $893,000,000.  Sixty-three  per- 
cent of  the  capitalization  ^^  and  81  percent  of  the  common  stock  of 
those  companies  was  owned  in  foreign  countries.  In  other  words 
control  was  held  through  the  ownership  of  the  common  stock  while 
United  States  capital  was  associated  in  the  enterprises  to  a  greater 
degree  through  the  ownership  of  preferred  stocks  and  bonds  than  of 
common  stock.  The  total  foreign  investment  in  the  37  companies 
with  assets  of  over  $10,000,000  amounted  to  $985,000,000,  or  73  per- 

"  Hearings  before  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  Part  G,  Liquor  Indus- 
try, p.  2537. 

"  Slost  of  the  larger  foreign-controlled  units  were  affiliated  with  foreign  corporations 
which  were  in  their  own  countries  considered  among  the  bigger  organizations. 

"  Capitalization  included  common  and  preferred  stock,  surplus  or  drflcit,  and  bonds  but 
excluded  advances  and  intercompany  accounts  and  other  current  liabilities. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  BCON'OMIO  POWER 


109 


cent  of  the  investment  in  the  651  companies,  and  64  percent  of  the 
total  foreign  direct  investments  in  the  United  States,  excluding  the 
insurance  companies. 

Table  VI. — Financial  structure  of  foreign  direct  investments '  in  the  United 
States,  by  industrial  groups  and  by  Geographic  areas,  end  of  19S7 

[In  millions  of  dollars] 


Industry  and  geographic  area 

Common 
stock 

Surplus 
account 

Preferred 
stock 

Bonds 
and  notes 

Advances 
and  inter- 
company 
accounts 

Total 

Industrial  groups: 

Manufacturing.   .    _. 

346 

41 

73 

3 

217 

5 

19 
1 
18 

202 
11 

(54) 

1 

35 

4 

12 
(1) 
3 

57 
12 
44 

1 
15 

1 

1 

i' 

32 
3 

91 

3 

2 

50 
20 
67 

687 

Distribution    

87 

Transportation 

221 

Public  utilities 

6 

Petroleum 

271 

Mining.  

U 

Finance 

33 

Agriculture 

4 

7 

Miscellaneous 

24 

Total 

723 

213 

132 

138 

141 

1,347 

Geographic  areas: 

United  Kingdom 

289 
130 
304 

118 

7 
88 

30 
61 
41 

14 
16 

8 

53 
71 
17 

504 

Canada ...  . 

385 

All  other  areas 

458 

Total .. 

723 

213 

132 

138 

141 

1,347 

'  Covering  651  companies  and  88  percent  of  the  total  foreign  direct  investments  in  the  United  States. 

The  financial  structure  of  foreign  direct  investments  in  the  United 
States  in  1937  differed  greatly  from  that  of  United  States  corpora- 
tions generally.  Over  53  percent  of  the  foreign  interest  took  the  form 
of  common  stock.  An  additional  16  percent  was  surplus,  while  pre- 
ferred stocks,  bonds,  and  advances  and  intercompany  accounts  each 
comprised  close  to  10  percent.  On  the  average,  corporate  structures 
in  the  United  States  in  1937  were  about  as  follows :  common,  25  per- 
cent; surplus,  15  percent;  preferred  stocks,  6  percent;  bonds,  notes, 
and  mortgages,  20  percent ;  and  accounts  payable  and  other  liabilities 
the  remainder,  or  34  percent.^* 

Such  a  financial  structure  cannot  be  considered  unusual  in  a  group 
of  companies  such  as  these ;  that  is,  companies  that  are  controlled  by 
other  companies  rather  than  by  individuals.  It  is  not  greatly  dif- 
ferent from  the  financial  structure  of  United  States  direct  investments 
in  foreign  countries.  The  distribution  in  the  latter  case  in  1936  was 
common  stock,  47.1  percent;  surplus,  13.6  percent;  preferred  stock, 
7  percent;  bonds,  18.2  percent;  and  advances  and  intercompany  ac- 
counts, 14.1  percent.^^  The  principal  difference  between  this  distribu- 
tion and  that  relating  to  foreign  direct  investments  in  the  United 
States  may  be  explained  very  largely  by  the  industrial  character  of 
ihe  two  sets  of  data.  The  principal  explanation  is  that  public  utility 
and  transportation  enterprises,  which  were  a  larger  part  of  direct 
investments  in  foreign  countries  than  of  direct  investments  in  the 
United  States,  are  normally  financed  more  largely  by  bonds,  pre- 
ferred stocks,  and  advances  than  are  other  industries. 

^*  Based  on  data  compiled  by  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue  from  the  reports  of 
•corporations  submitting  balance  sheets. 

1^  Department  of  Commerce,  Economic  Series  No.  1,  American  Direct  Investments  in 
Foreign  Countries — 1936,  by  Paul  D.  Dickens,  pp.  22-24. 


CONCLUSION 

The  data  herein  presented  show  that,  on  the  whole,  foreign  cartels 
and  foreign  corporations  exerted  only  a  minor  influence  on  production 
in  this  country  in  1937.  Cartel  members,  rather  than  the  cartel  or- 
ganizations themselves,  were  the  sources  of  the  only  part  of  such 
control  that  was  found  to  exist.  They  did  not  dominate  any  strategic 
industry  and  did  not  give  rise  to  any  serious  problems.  In  general, 
it  may  be  said  that  foreign  control  of  United  States  industry,  which 
was  so  extensive  during  much  of  the  nineteenth  century,  has  by 
the  gradual  and  natural  process  of  repatriation,  been  effectively 
eliminated. 
110 


PART  III 

REPORT  OF  THE  FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION  ON  THE 

OPERATION  OF  THE  EXPORT  TRADE  ACT 

(WEBB-POMERENE  LAW)  1918-1940 

Submitted  by 
THE  FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION 


111 


REPORT  OF  THE  FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION  ON  THE 

OPERATION  OF  THE  EXPORT  TRADE  ACT  (WEBB- 

POMERENE  LAW— 1918-40) 

BACKGROUND 

REPORT  OF  THE  FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION   ON   COOPERATION   IN 
AMERICAN    EXPORT   TRADE,    1910 

The  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act  was  passed  on  September  26. 
1914,  and  the  Commissioners  took  the  oath  of  office  on  March  16, 1915. 
In  May  of  1915  an  inquiry  was  begun  under  section  6  (h)  of  the  act 
on  trade  conditions  in  and  with  foreign  countries  which  might  affect 
the  foreign  trade  of  this  country.  Informal  hearings  were  held  in 
Boston  and  New  York  in  June  of  that  year.  Arrangements  were 
made  with  the  Department  of  State  for  assistance  of  the  United 
States  consuls,  and  with  the  Department  of  Commerce,  for  cooper- 
ation of  the  connnercial  attaches  stationed  abroad.^ 

During  the  following  year  the  hearings  were  extended  to  other 
parts  of  the  country — Chicago,  Detroit,  Cincinnati,  Indianapolis, 
St.  Paul,  Spokane,  Seattle,  Tacoma,  Portland  (Oreg.),  San  Fran- 
cisco, Los  Angeles,  San  Diego,  and  other  cities.  Questionnaires  were 
sent  to  several  thcMisand  corporations,  firms,  associations,  and  indi- 
viduals interested  in  the  subject,  and  field  inquiries  were  made.  Re- 
ports were  received  from  American  consuls  and  commercial  attaches, 
and  a  Connnission  investigator  was  sent  to  South  America.  A  study 
was  made  of  cartels,  syndicates,  and  combinations  in  foreign  coun- 
tries, including  i)rice  and  export  agreements  of  foreign  combines. 
Results  of  this  inquiry  were  described  by  the  Commission  as  "the 
most  comprehensive  presentation  of  facts  relating  to  the  questioi' 
of  combination  and  cooperation  as  it  affects  international  trade  that 
is  anywhere  available."  ^ 

The  Commission's  report  on  "Cooperation  in  American  Export 
Trade''  in  two  volumes  was  presented  to  Congress  on  June  30,  1916.* 
It  recommended  the  passage  of  a  law  to  permit  cooperation  in  export 
trade,  iri  order  that  American  exporters  should  be  enabled  to  compete 
in  foreign  markets  on  more  nearly  equal  terms  with  foreign  com- 
petitors. Since  the  report  is  now  out  of  print,  excerpts  will  be 
quoted  therefrom : 

The  importance  of  our  foreigu  commerce  and  the  need  of  understanding  the 
conditions  American  exporters  must  meet  in  competing  for  the  trade  of  the 
world  was  recognized  by  Congress  when  it  gave  the  Federal  Trade  Commission 
wide  power  to  investigate  and  to  report  its  recommendations  regarding  hose 
conditions     *     *     *     (p.  11,  vol.  1). 


1  A'Rnaal  report  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  1915,  pp.  1,  2. 
'  Annual  report  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  1916,  p.  20. 

'Report  on   "Cooperation  in  American   Export  Trade,"  two  volumes,   1916   (now  out   of 
print). 

113 


j]^4  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

In  view  of  the  convulsive  effect  of  the  present  war  on  the  commerce  of  the 
world  and  of  the  difficulty  of  foreseeing  the  economic  and  business  conditions  that 
will  result  after  the  treaties  of  peace,  the  Commission  has  deemed  it  its  duty  to 
complete,  with  all  possible  dispatch,  an  investigation  of  the  obstacles  which  have 
heretofore  confronted  American  manufacturers  and  producers  in  world  markets, 
and  recommend  such  legislation  by  Congress  as  will  best  enable  them  to  at  least 
hold  their  ground  in  the  fierce  commercial  struggle  that  seems  imminent  after 
the  war  is  over. 

The  economic  map  of  the  world  is  being  remade.  The  businessmen  of  the 
world  are  seeking  to  forecast  conditions  and  to  readjust  affairs  to  the  greatest 
advantage.  The  next  few  years  contain  possibilities  of  as  far-reaching  and 
enduring  consequence  to  American  industry,  commerce,  and  finance  as  perhaps 
any  years  in  the  history  of  the  country  (p.  11,  vol.  1). 

One  of  the  facts  that  stands  out  sharply  as  the  result  of  the  Commission's 
inquiry  is  the  strength  and  character  of  the  demand  for  cooperation  among 
manufacturers  and  producers  in  export  business.  Four-fifths  of  all  replies 
received  were  in  favor  of  such  joint  action.  These  replies  represented  all  interests 
and  sections  of  business  and  professional  men  in  the  country,  manufacturers, 
wholesalers,  jobbers,  retailers,  export  commission  houses,  manufacturers'  exiwrt 
agents,  importers,  lawyers,  economists,  publicists,  engineers,  contractors,  etc. 
They  furnish  a  striking  expression  of  the  convictions  of  these  men  whose  knowl- 
edge and  experience  of  competitive  conditions  in  international  markets  dictated 
their  answers  (pp.  199,  200,  vol.  1). 

Another  noteworthy  fact  in  connection  with  this  demand  is  the  attitude  of 
the  smaller  manufacturers  and  producers.  They  have  felt  keenly  their  disad- 
vantage in  attempting  to  enter  foreign  marketa  single-handed  in  the  face  of  the 
powerful,  united,  and  long-established  competitors  of  other  nations.  They  realize 
that  for  them  export  trade  must  be  done  largely  through  the  medium  of  export 
commission  houses  and  export  merchants.  But  they  realize  the  advantages — in 
some  cases  the  necessity — of  their  own  direct  representation  and  their  own 
foreign  organizations  if  they  are  to  build  up  an  enduring  export  trade.  At  present 
cooperation  with  the  other  small  manufacturers  is  the  best  solution  of  the  dif- 
ficulty before  them. 

They  desire  in  some  instances  to  combine  with  noncompeting  but  complemen- 
tary manufacturers  to  conduct  joint  foreign  selling  campaigns  and  establish 
foreign  selling  agencies     *     *     *. 

In  other  cases  small  producers  of  competing  products  desire  to  form  joint 
exporting  agencies,  where  such  concerted  action  is  manifestly  to  their  mutual 
advantage  in  the  promotion  of  export  business. 

At  this  point  it  is  well  to  call  attention  to  the  fact  that  in  many  lines  there  is 
need  of  direct  representation  of  manufacturers  in  foreign  business.  In  some 
cases  the  export  commission  houses  are  well  fitted  to  introduce  and  develop 
foreign  trade,  but  in  many  line.s  of  manufacture  they  are  inferior  for  this  pur- 
pose to  the  manufacturers  own  agents.  This  is  especially  true  of  products  such 
as  many  kinds  of  machinery,  electrical  supplies,  and  equipment,  etc.,  .which 
require  special  demonstration  and  installation.  In  general  it  isi  to  be  expected 
that  a  manufacturer,  who  has  capital  invested  in  plants  and  equipment  and  must 
market  his  output,  will  push  the  sales  of  his  goods  more  vigorously  than  any 
outside  party  who  has  no  such  investment  and  whose  business  includes  the  sale 
of  many  other  wares.  In  one  case  energy  and  effort  and  purpose  are  divided ; 
in  the  other  they  are  concentrated. 

While  much  of  the  export  business  of  smaller  manufacturers  will  continue  to 
be  done  by  export  houses,  nevertheless  direct  representation  will  in  many  cases 
have  a  decided  advantage.  The  smaller  American  businessmen  frequently  em- 
phasize the  fact  that  the  most  efficient  American  exporting  organizations  are 
those  of  a  few  of  the  great  corporations,  whose  resources  permit  the  maintenance 
of  direct  representation.  They  complain  that  their  lack  of  concerted  action 
prevents  them  from  developing  similar  effective  joint  exporting  organizations  of 
their  own  and  results  in  giving  the  larger  American  companies  an  undue  share 
of  the  export  trade. 

The  Commission  has  been  strongly  impressed  with  the  effect  that  the  doubt 
as  to  the  application  of  the  antitrust  law  has  had  in  the  formation  of  cooperative 
export  organizations  among  Amoiican  manufacturers  and  producers.  There  are 
a  few  such  organizations,  but  they  are  nearly  all  among  noncompetitors.  Most 
manufacturers  decline  to  join  any  sucli  ai^s'irfation  or  cooperative  organization  so 
long  as  there  is  any  doubt  as  to  its  legality.  This  is  true  even  of  those  who  believe 
such  organizations  legal  for  export  trade.    It  thus  results  that  this  doubt  acts  as 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  115 

an  effective  preventive  of  the  formation  of  cooperative  export  organizations 
among  manufacturers  and  producers,  and  particularly  keeps  tlie  smaller  business 
concerns  from  participating  in  foreign  trade  as  freely  as  they  should  (pp.  200, 
201,  vol.  1). 

The  Commission  called  attention  to  the  fact  that  in  foreign  coun- 
tries combinations  or  cartels  of  producers  and  dealers  were  well  estab- 
lished; and  American  exporters  must  meet  the  competition  of  these 
groups : 

In  seeking  business  abroad  American  manufacturers  and  producers  must  meet 
aggressive  competition  from  jjovperful  foreign  combinations,  often  interna- 
tional in  character.  In  Germany,  Italy,  Switzerland,  Holland,  Sweden,  Belgium, 
Japan,  and  certain  other  countries  where  policies  concerning  industrial  com- 
binations are  quite  diverse  from  that  of  the  United  States,  businessmen  are 
much  freer  to  cooperate  and  combine  than  in  this  country.  They  have  de- 
veloped numerous  comprehensive  combinations,  sometimes  aided  by  their  Gov- 
ernments, which  effectually  unite  their  activities  both  in  domestic  and  foreign 
trade.  In  England  and  Austria-Hungary,  though  freedom  to  combine  is  con- 
siderably abridged  under  the  law,  important  combinations  have  also  been 
formed. 

In  Germany  prior  to  the  war  there  were  600  important  cartels,  i.  e.,  com- 
binations to  control  the  market,  embracing  practically  every  industry  in  the 
Empire.  Many  dominated  the  export  trade  of  their  industries  and  carried 
on  vigorous  campaigns  to  extend  their  foreign  business,  to  prevent  competition 
among  German  producers  in  foreign  markets,  and  to  secure  profitable  prices. 
Thus  the  German  dye-color  industry  operated  as  a  unit  in  foreign  trade  under 
the  leadership  of  two  great  groups  of  allied  producers,  the  Badische  group  and 
the  Hochst-Cassella,  which  were  working  under  a  50-year  agreement  to  avoid 
competition  between  themselves.  The  manufacture  and  exportation  of  electrical 
equipment  has  been  made  one  of  the  bulwarks  of  German  foreign  trade  by  two 
great  companies,  the  Allgemeine  Elektricitats-Gesellschaft  and  the  Siemens- 
Schuckert,  working  in  harmony  with  each  other,  with  numerous  subsidiaries  at 
home  and  abroad.  Half  of  the  $150,000,000  worth  of  coal  and  coke  exported  an- 
nually was  sold  by  one  central  selling  agency  maintained  by  the  great  RheinLsch- 
Westfalische  coal  syndicate,  of  which  some  of  the  Prussian  Government  mines 
are  members,  and  which  controlled  the  bulk  of  all  the  coal  and  coke  produced 
in  the  Empire.  Practically  all  the  rapidly  increasing  iron  and  steel  export  busi- 
ness was  handled  respectively  by  the  single  selling  agencies  of  the  Roheisen- 
Verband  and  the  Stahlwerks-Verband,  the  aggressive  and  closely  connected  unions 
of  German  iron  and  steel  manufacturers.  The  coal  and  iron  and  steel  com- 
binations have  fostered  foreign  business  through  export  bounties  and  other 
means. 

In  France  and  Belgium,  syndicates  of  iron  and  steel,  glass,  and  other  industries 
were  strong  factors  in  domestic  and  foreign  trade.  Silk-ribbon  manufacturers 
of  France  and  Germany  conducted  their  export  trade  in  accordance  with  a 
joint  agreement.  In  Italy,  Russia,  Austria-Hungary,  Switzerland,  Sweden, 
Greece,  Argentina.  Chile,  and  Ecuador,  central  organizations  unite  the  interests 
of  producers  in  the  industries  characteristic  of  those  countries,  such  as  coal, 
iron  and  steel,  agricultural  machinery,  oil,  sulfur,  superphosphates,  cement, 
matches,  chocolate,  embroidery,  silk  goods,  watches,  cotton  goods,  condensed 
milk,  canned  fish,  currants,  quebracho,  iodine,  cacao,  etc. 

In  Japan  an  export  organization  of  textile  nianufaturers  is  rapidly  obtaining 
the  extensive  cotton  goods  trade  of  North  China.  The  trade  in  tea  is  con- 
trolled by  a  nation-wide  "tea  council."  One  great  Japanese  firm,  which  in  itself 
combines  manufacturing,  mining,  shipping,  and  merchandising  enterprises,  is 
rapidly  extending  Japanese  trade  in  all  lines  throughout  the  Far  East,  and  the 
Japanese  Government  is  directly  assisting  the  development  of  shipping,  banking, 
and  trading  for  foreign  business. 

The  long-established  trade  in  British  products  in  many  markets  of  the  world, 
due  to  their  pioneer  position,  the  excellent  representation  afforded  by  British 
export  houses,  and  the  advantages  of  British  shipping  and  banking  facilities, 
have  enabled  their  manufacturers  to  hold  their  foreign  markets  in  many  lines 
without  such  a  large  degree  of  combination  as  characterizes  German  industry. 
But  in  various  important  industries  combinations  have  grown  up.  Thus  most  of 
the   great  coal  export  business  is  done  by  powerful   organizations,   combining 

2.57760 — 41 — No.  6 0 


216  OONCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

mine  operators,  marketing  companies,  coal  shipping  lines,  and  foreign  dis- 
tributing companies.  This  gives  British  coal  its  grip  on  the  important  South 
American  market.  British  cement  manufacturers  are  united  in  a  strong  and 
successful  union  for  the  extension  of  their  overseas  trade.  Recently  a  number 
of  large  British  manufacturers  of  machinery  of  all  sorts  have  formed  the  Rep- 
resentation for  British  Manufacturers,  Ltd.,  an  organization  to  handle  their 
business  in  certain  important  foreign  markets  and  to  carry  on  an  aggressive 
campaign  for  its  extension.  Similar  organizations  for  foreign  trade  are  in 
process  of  formation  among  other  British  manufacturers.  In  the  electrical,  cot- 
ton textile,  pottery,  tobacco,  wallpaper,  iron  and  steel,  and  various  other  in- 
dustries strong  associations  and  combinations  are  important  factors  in  foreign 
and  domestic  business. 

It  is  against  such  organizations  as  these,  uniting  powerful  groups  of  foreign 
concerns,  backed  by  great  banks,  aided  by  railway  and  ship  lines,  and  assisted 
by  foreign  governments,  that  hundreds  of  comparatively  small  American  manu- 
facturers and  producers  must  compete  if  they  engage  in  export  trade.  More- 
over, in  some  industries  such  smaller  manufacturers  must  also  compete  abroad 
with  great  American  companies  having  most  efficient  world-wide  selling  organi- 
zations. 

In  varioiis  manufacturing  industries  high  manufacturing  costs  and  com- 
parative inexperience  in  export  trade  make  it  extremely  difficult  at  best  for 
Americans  to  compete  with  foreigners  for  trade  abroad.  Therefore,  meeting 
severe  competition  from  powerful  foreign  combinations,  and  through  dependence 
on  foreign  cables,  telegraphs,  banks,  and  ships  forced  to  risk  exposure  of  the 
secrets  of  their  overseas  business  to  their  foreign  competitors  and  to  risk  effective 
discrimination  against  their  trade,  American  manufacturers,  and  especially  the 
smaller  producers,  are  frequently  at  a  decisive  disadvantage  in  export  trade 
(pp.  4  to  7,  vol.  1). 

The  Commission's  report  also  stated  that  American  exporters  were 
in  many  countries  selling  to  buying  combinations  or  cartels: 

In  various  markets  American  manufacturers  and  producers  must  deal  with 
highly  effective  combinations  of  foreign  buyers.  Thus  exporters  of  lumber 
find  such  combinations  in  Australia  and  on  the  continent  of  Europe.  Cotton- 
seed products  are  handled  by  combinations  of  buyers  in  Holland,  Denmark,  and 
Germany ;  and  Austrian  cotton-textile  manufacturers  have  a  buying  combina- 
tion to  import  their  raw  cotton.  The  Cooperative  Wholesale  Society,  Ltd.,  an 
astonishingly  comprehensive  wholesale  buying  organization  maintained  by 
1,400  cooperative  societies  in  Great  Britain,  has  one  buyer  in  New  York  who 
annually  purchases  millions  of  dollars'  worth  of  American  products.  Four 
London  firms,  known  as  the  Fixing  Board,  daily  set  the  price  of  silver  for  the 
world,  and  American  mining  companies  must  sell  their  silver  for  either  the 
English  or  the  great  Indian  market  to  one  of  these  four  houses.  For  years 
the  copper  trade  "of  the  world  has  been  ruled  by  a  vast  German  metal-buying 
organization  centering  in  the  Metallbank  und  Metallurgische  Gesellschaft  A.  G. 
of  Frankfort-on-the-Main.  This  combination  has  subsidiary  and  affiliated 
companies  in  Germany,  England,  France,  Spain,  Switzerland,  Belgium,  Africa, 
and  Australia,  contrcds  copper  and  lead  mines  and  smelters  in  the  United  States, 
Mexico,  and  other  countries,  and  works  in  agreement  with  other  German  metal- 
buying  concerns. 

These  combinations  naturally  make  individual  American  producers  bid  against 
each  other,  and  are  thus  able  to  buy  at  comparatively  low  prices.  Accord- 
ing to  the  president  of  one  of  the  largest  American  copper  companies,  the 
German  metal-buying  combination,  by  such  tactics  as  these  and  by  the  manipu- 
lation of  the  foreign  future  markets,  has  bought  millions  of  tons  of  American 
copper  at  prices  averaging,  over  a  series  of  years,  nearly  a  cent  a  pound  below 
the  prices  paid  by  American  consumers  (p.  7,  vol.  1). 

The  advantages  of  cooperation  in  American  export  trade  were 
stated : 

If  Americans  are  to  enter  the  markets  of  the  world  on  more  nearly  equal 
terms  with  their  organized  competitors  and  their  organized  customers,  and  if 
small  American  producers  and  manufacturers  are  to  engage  in  export  trade  on 
profitable  terms,  they  must  be  free  to  unite  their  efforts. 

"Vyithout  any  export  organization,  foodstuffs  and  raw  materials  can  readily  be 
sold   at   some  price,   but  to   avoid   needless   expense   in   distribution,    to   meet 


CJONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  117 

formidable  foreign  buying  orgianizations,  and  to  insure  profitable  export  prices, 
cooperation  among  American  producers  of  such  commodities  is  desirable. 

In  the  sale  of  factory  products,  cooperation  is  even  more  desirable.  Such 
goods  must  be  advertised,  demonstrated,  and  a  market  created  abroad,  often  in 
the  face  of  the  keenest  competition  from  great  combinations  of  foreign  manu- 
facturers. Obviously  only  strong  organizations  can  undertake  this  contest.  If 
groups  of  American  manufacturers  and  producers,  either  of  competing  or  of 
noncompeting  goods,  can  combine  their  efforts,  they  can  share  the  cost  of 
developing  new  markets,  establish  themselves  firmly,  extend  credit  more  readily 
to  foreign  customers,  and  compete  more  successfully  with  foreign  syndicates 
and  cartels  (p.  8,  vol.  1). 

There  ar"  relatively  few  manufacturing  corporations  in  the  United  States 
whose  foreign  trade  is  more  than  a  small  fraction  of  their  domestic  trade. 
By  securing  a  broader  market  for  his  output  the  American  manufacturer 
should  not  only,  through  enlarging  the  capacity  of  his  works,  be  enabled,  to 
produce  at  a  lower  cost  per  unit,  but  there  would  also  be  an  increased  employ- 
ment of  labor.  Furthermore,  greater  stability  would  be  promoted  in  many  of 
the  industries.  With  a  broader  market,  periods  of  local  industrial  depression' 
have  less  effect  on  the  business  of  the  manufacturer.  In  some  industries  there- 
are  wide  differences  between  the  different  countries  in  the  seasonal  character 
of  their  demand.  For  example,  in  the  United  States  in  the  wintertime  the 
use  of  Portland  cement  falls  off,  and  as  a  result  the  manufacture  is  curtailed 
during  those  months.  This,  however,  is  summertime  in  Argentina  and  Chile, 
when  building  activity  is  at  its  height.  Could  those  markets  be  secured  for 
American  cement  the  cement  producers  would  have  a  better  opportunity  to 
steady  their  production,  keep  their  workmen  more  regularly  employed,  and 
lower  their  operating  costs  by  manufacturing  and  exporting  their  product 
during  the  dull  domestic  season.  At  the  time  when  summer  is  coming  on  in 
the  United  States,  and  the  demand  for  coal  is  declining,  the  South  American 
winter  is  just  beginning.  What  is  true  of  the  seasonal  fluctuation  of  demand 
in  cement  and  coal  also  applies  to  various  other  commodities  (pp.  23,  24, 
vol.  1). 

The  Commission's  recommendations  to  Congress  are  summarized 
on  the  last  pages  of  the  1916  report : 

Section  3. — Recommendations  of  the  Commission. — The  Commission  believes 
that  American  exporters  should  be  enabled  to  compete  in  foreign  markets  on 
more  nearly  equal  terms  with  foreign  competitors.  It  also  believes  that  the 
smaller  manufacturers  and  producers,  so  far  as  they  desire,  should  be  enabled 
to  share  in  such  foreign  business.  It  is  convinced  that  for  these  purposes 
cooperation  in  export  trade  should  be  permitted.  It  knows  that  doubt  as  to 
the  application  of  the  antitrust  laws  now  prevents  any  marked  developmejit  of 
such  cooi)eration.  It  does  not  believe  that  Congress  intended  by  the  anti- 
trust laws  to  prevent  Americans  from  cooperating  in  export  trade  for  the- 
purpose  of  competing  effectively  with  foreigners  where  such  cooperation  does 
not  restrain  trade  within  the  United  States  and  where  no  effort  is  made  to 
hinder  American  competitors  from  freely  engaging  in  export  trade.  It  is 
not  reasonable  to  suppose  that  Congress  meant  to  obstruct  the  development 
of  foreign  commerce  by  forbidding  the  use  in  export  trade  of  methods  of 
organization  which  do  not  operate  to  the  prejudice  of  the  American  public, 
which  are  lawful  in  the  countries  where  the  trade  is  to  be  carried  on,  and 
which  are  necessary  if  greater  equality  of  opportunity  is  to  be  afforded 
Americans  in  meeting  foreign  competitors.  The  Commission,  therefore,  re- 
spectfully recommends  that  Congress  enact  declaratory  and  permissive  legis- 
lation to  remove  the  present  doubt  as  to  the  law  and  to  establish  clearly 
the  legality  of  such  cooperation. 

The  Commission  is  aware  that  certain  dangers  may  arise  from  the  devel- 
opment of  cooperative  export  organizations.  As  has  been  pointed  out,  there 
are  two  chief  dangers:  First,  they  may  be  used  to  exploit  consumers  in  the 
home  market;  and,  second,  they  may  be  used  unfairly  against  individual 
American  concerns  in  export  trade  that  are  not  members  of  the  organiza- 
tions. These  dangers  must  be  provided  against  fully,  and  the  Commission 
is  confident  that  this  can  be  done  without  sacrificing  any  of;  the  essential 
advantages  of  concerted  action  and  without  altering  the  fundamental  policy 
of  the  antitrust  laws  or  interfering  with  their  enforcement. 

As  safeguards  against  the  dangers  of  such  organizations  it  is  recommended 


118  OONCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

specifically  that  the  kind  of  cooperative  associations  or  organizations  permit- 
ted be  clearly  defined;  that  they  be  restricted  solely  to  export  business  as 
■distinguished  from  domestic  business;  that  they  be  limited  to  the  activities 
of  selling  goods  as  distinguished  from  their  production  or  manufacture;  and 
that  the  term  "export  trade"  be  defined  to  mean  solely  trade  or  commerce 
in  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise  exported  and  be  specifically  stated  not  to  include 
the  production  or  manufacture  of  such  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise  or  any 
act  in  their  production  or  manufacture.  It  is  also  recommended  that  as  a 
condition  precedent  to  enjoying  the  benefit  of  such  legislation  every  such 
cooperative  organization  be  required,  under  penalty,  to  file  promptly  with 
the  Federal '  Trade  Commission  a  written  statement  setting  forth  the  essen- 
tial facts  concerning  its  organization,  such  as  name,  location  of  its  ofiices  and 
places  of  business,  names  and  addresses  of  its  ofticers  and  stockholders  or 
members,  and  a  copy  of  its  articles  of  incorporation  and  bylaws,  if  incor- 
porated, or  a  copy  of  its  articles  of  contract  or  association,  if  unincorporated. 
The  Commission  has  the  authority  now  to  require  such  reports,  but  it  should 
not  be  burdened  with  the  work  of  discovering  such  organizations  and  request- 
ing information  from  them.  The  burden  of  furnishing  the  required  facts  as 
to  their  organization  should  rest  upon  those  who  expect  to  enjoy  the  benefit  of 
this  law.  Having  these  facts  before  it,  the  Commission  could  then  use  the 
power  it  already  has  to  require  other  reports  in  such  detail  as  may  be  neces- 
sary to  inform  it  fully  of  the  activities  of  such  cooperative  bodies  and  to  place 
it  in  a  position  to  take  such  action  as  the  public  interest  might  require. 

It  is  also  recommended,  in  order  that  there  may  be  no  possible  doubt  about 
the  law,  that  the  prohibitions  concerning  the  use  of  unfair  methods  of  compe- 
tition contained  in  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act  be  si)ecifically  extended 
to  apply  to  export  trade,  even  tliough  the  acts  constituting  such  unfair  meth- 
ods be  done  outside  of  the  territorial  jurisdiction  of  the  United  States. 

Restrictions  and  safeguards  of  these  kinds  have  been  suggested  and  advised 
by  the  great  majority  of  the  thousands  of  businessmen  reached  by  the  Com- 
mission in  its  study.  Manufacturers  generally  express  no  wish  to  attempt 
to  use  such  organizations  to  exploit  the  market  at  home,  but  indicate  their  de- 
sire to  see  any  such  attempt  guarded  against.  Moreover,  numerous  manufac- 
turers state  that,  owing  to  the  nature  of  their  products,  or  to  the  fact  that  they 
are  already  well  established  in  foreign  markets,  they  themselves  would  not 
care  to  join  cooperative  export  organizations  but  that  they  realize  their  value 
for  many  other  lines  and  are  in  favor  of  them.  They  merely  ask  that  they 
themselves  be  assured  against  unfair  methods  of  competition  from  such  or- 
ganizations. The  businessmen  who  have  expressed  opposition  to  such  restrictive 
safeguards  are  relatively  few. 

In  making  these  recommendations  the  Commission  does  not  intend  to  intimate 
that  there  should  be  any  change  in  the  present  policy  of  this  Government  to 
prevent  combinations  in  restraint  of  trade  in  domestic  business  and  to  insist 
upon  fair  competition  in  such  business. 

The  Commission  is  confident  that  the  enactment  of  such  legislation  as  that  out- 
lined above  will  permit  the  development  of  the  cooperative  organization  which 
must  take  place  if  the  manufacturers  and  producers  of  the  United  States  are  to 
compete  with  foreigners  on  more  equal  terms  in  export  trade.  It  is  also  confi- 
dent that  this  essential  development  can  be  obtained  without  haimful  effects  on 
the  domestic  market  and  without  prejudice  to  the  interests  of  American  concerns 
which  conduct  their  exjxjrt  business  outside  of  any  combination  (pp.  379  381, 
vol.  1). 

DEBATES  IN  CONGRESS,  HEARINGS,  AND  COMMITTEE  REPORTS 

Bills  were  introduced  in  Congress  by  Senator  Atlee  Pomerene  and 
Congressman  Edwin  Y.  Webb  (the  act  is  therefore  referred  to  as  the 
Webb-Pomerene  law),  and  were  considered  by  congressional  commit- 
tees and  debates  in  Congress  in  1916,  1917,  and  1918,  finally  becoming 
a  law  in  April  1918.  They  were  endorsed,  not  only  by  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission  but  also  by  President  Wilson,  Secretary  of  Com- 
merce Redfield,  numerous  trade  organizations  such  as  the  National 
Foreign  Trade  Council,  American  Manufacturers  Export  Association, 


OONCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  J 19 

and  the  chambers  of  commerce;  and  also  by  representatives  of  the 
various  industries.* 

THE  LAW  AS  PASSED  ON  APRIL  10,1918 

The  law  as  passed  on  April  10,  1918,''  is  entitled  "An  Act  to  Pro- 
mote Export  Trade  and  for  Other  Purposes." 

Section  1  defines  the  words  "export  trade,"  "trade  within  the 
United  States,"  and  "association"  wherever  used  in  the  act.  Especial 
care  was  taken  in  defining  export  trade : 

the  words  "export  trade"  wherever  used  in  this  act  mean  solely  trade  or  com- 
merce in  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise  exported,  or  in  the  course  of  being  ex- 
ported, from  the  United  States  or  any  Territory  thereof  to  any  foreign  nation ; 
but  the  words  "export  trade"  shall  not  be  deemed  to  include  the  production, 
manufacture,  or  selling  for  consumption  or  for  resale,  within  the  United  States 
or  any  Territory  thereof,  of  such  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise,  or  any  act  in 
the  course  of  such  production,  manufacture,  or  selling  for  consumption  or  for 
resale. 

The  bill  H.  R.  17350,  as  first  drafted,  and  as  recommended  by  the 
House  Committee  on  the  Judiciary  in  1916,  provided  that — 

the  words  "export  trade"  shall  not  be  deemed  to  include  the  production  or  man- 
ufacture within  the  United  States  or  any  Territory  thereof  of  such  goods,  wares^ 
or  merchandise,  or  any  act  in  the  course  of  such  production  or  manufacture. 

To  this  was  added  by  amendment  the  words  "trading  in  or  mar- 
keting" so  that  the  bill  as  passed  by  the  House  on  September  2,  1916, 
read : 

the  words  "export  trade"  shall  not  be  deemed  to  include  the  production,  manu- 
facture, trading  in,  or  marketing  within  the  United  States  or  any  Territory 
thereof  of  such  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise,  or  any  act  in  the  course  of  such 
production  or  manufacture. 

This  was  objected  to  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  and  others. 
In  its  annual  report  to  Congress  in  1916  the  Commission  said : 

In  order  to  permit  cooperation  only  with  respect  to  esport  trade,  the  term 
"export  trade"  was  originally  carefully  defined  to  exclude  the  production  or 
manufacture  of  goods  within  the  United  States,  but  the  amendment  made  it 
also  exclude  "trading  in  or  marketing"  such  good?  within  the  United  States. 
•  *  *  Obviously  a  successful  cooperative  export  organiaztion  would,  in  most 
cases,  be  obliged  to  purchase  goods  in  the  United  States  and  therefore  to  trade 
in  them.* 

This  clause  "trading  in  or  marketing"  was  therefore  deleted  from 
the  bill,  and  the  clause  "or  selling  for  consumption  or  for  resale"  was 


*  H.  R.  16707,  Congressman  Webb,  64th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  1916.  H.  R.  17350,  Congress- 
man Webb,  64th  Cong.,  2d  sess.,  1916.  H.  R.  2316,  Congressman  Webb,  65th  Cong,  (same 
as  S.  634,  Senator  Pomerene),  passed  both  Houses,  signed  in  1918.  Hearings  before  House 
Committee  on  the  Judiciary  on  H.  R.  16707  and  copy  of  bill  and  report,  serial  48,  64th 
Cong.,  1st  sess.,  July  1916,  85  pp.  Hearings  before  Senate  Committee  on  Interstate  Com- 
merce, 64th  Cong.,  2d  sess.,  on  H.  R.  17350,  January  1917,  156  pp.  Rept.  No.  1118,  64th 
Cong.,  1st  sess..  House  Committee  on  the  Judiciary,  to  accompany  H.  R.  17.S50,  August  15, 
1916,  4  pp.  Rept.  No.  1056,  64th  Cong.,  2d  sess..  Senate  Committee  on  Interstate  Com- 
merce, to  accompany  H.  R.  17350-,  February  14,  1917,  4  pp.  Rept.  No.  9,  65th  Cong.,  1st 
sess.,  to  accompany  S.  634,  Senate  Committee  on  Interstate  Commerce,  April  16,  l9l7,  4 
pp.  Rept.  No.  50,  65th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  to  accompany  H.  R.  2316,  House  Committee  on 
the  Judiciary,  May  11.  1917,  10  pp.  Rept.  No.  109,  65th  Cong.,  1st  sess..  Senate  Com- 
mittee on  Interstate  Commerce,  to  accompany  H.  R.  2316,  August  15,  1917,  4  pp.  House 
of  Representatives  Rept.  No.  468,  65th  Cong.  2d  sess.,  conference  report  to  accompany 
H.  R.  2316,  April  5,  1918.  Debates,  64th  Cong.,  June,  August,  and  September  1916  ;  65tb 
Cong.,  May,  June,  September,  and  December  1917,  January  and  April  1918. 

"  40  Stat.  516,  text  in  appendix  1   herewith. 

•  Annual  Rept.  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  1916,  pp.  35,  36. 


120  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

substituted  therefor.  This  is  explained  by  the  Senate  Committee  on 
Interstate  Commerce,  in  its  report  on  February  14,  1917 :  ^ 

All  seem  to  agree  that  export  trade  should  not  include  production  and  manu- 
facture. The  words  "trading  in  or  marketing"  would  permit  these  associa- 
tions to  compete  in  the  home  markets  where  combinations  in  restraint  of  trade 
are  forbidden.  We  substitute  for  this  phrase  the  words  "selling  for  consump- 
tion," so  that  this  part  of  the  text  will  read  "The  words  'export  trade'  shall  not 
be  deemed  to  include  the  production,  manufacture,  or  selling  for  consumption 
within  the  United  States,"  etc.  We  desire,  of  course,  to  authorize  associations 
for  the  sole  purpose  of  selling  abroad.  In  order  to  do  this,  they  must  have  the 
right  to  acquire  or  buy  within  the  United  States  and  the  right  to  sell  within  the 
United  States  for  the  foreign  market,  but  in  view  of  the  settled  domestic  policy 
of  the  United  States  under  the  Sherman  law,  clearly  these  associations  should 
not  be  permitted  to  organize  for  the  purpose  of  making  sales  abroad  and  use 
their  organizations  to  sell  for  consumption  within  the  United  States. 

The  Avord  "association"  is  specifically  defined  in  section  1  of  the 
act  as: 

any  corporation  or  combination,  by  contract  or  otherwise,  of  two  or  more  per- 
sons, partnerships,  or  corporations. 

Section  2  of  the  act  provides  that  nothing  contained  in  the 
Sherman  Act: 

shall  be  construed  as  declaring  to  be  illegal  an  association  entered  into  for  the 
sole  purpose  of  engaging  in  export  trade  and  actually  engaged  solely  in  such 
export  trade,  or  an  agreement  made  or  act  done  in  the  course  of  export  trade 
by  such  association,  provided  such  association,  agreement,  or  act  is  not  in  re- 
straint of  trade  within  the  United  States,  and  is  not  in  restraint  of  the  export 
trade  of  any  domestic  competitor  of  such  association :  And  provided  further, 
That  such  association  does  not,  either  in  the  United  States  or  elsewhere,  enter 
into  any  agreement,  understanding,  or  conspiracy,  or  do  any  act  which  arti- 
ficially or  intentionally  enhances  or  depresses  prices  within  the  United  States 
of  commodities  of  the  class  exported  by  such  association,  or  which  substantially 
lessens  competition  within  the  United  States  or  otherwise  restrains  trade 
therein. 

This  section,  too,  was  changed  somewhat  before  the  law  was  passed. 
The  proviso  clause  as  originally  drafted  was : 

provided  such  association,  agreement,  or  act  is  not  in  restraint  of  trade  within 
the  United  States. 

To  this  was  added  by  amendment  in  the  House  in  1916 : 

and  does  not  restrain  the  export  trade  of  the  United  States. 

But  this  amendment  was  objected  to.  The  Commission  said,  in 
its  annual  report  to  Congress  in  1916:  ^ 

two  amendments  were  made  to  the  bill  during  the  debate  which  seem  to  give  a 
basis  for  legal  construction  which  might  entirely  nullify  this  purpose. 

The  first  amendment  referred  to  was  made  in  the  first  section  of  the 
bill.     *     *     * 

The  second  amendment  referred  to  is  found  in  the  second  section.  This 
originally  granted  the  right  of  cooperative  association  for  export  trade,  pro- 
vided such  association  did  not  involve  "restraint  of  trade  within  the  United 
States."  But  the  amendment  added  a  further  proviso,  namely,  "and  does  not 
restrain  the  ex]x»rt  trade  of  the  United  States."  *  *  *  The  Commission  is 
of  the  opinion  that  these  provisions  of  the  bill  would  not  change  the  present 
law.  But  the  very  purpose  of  the  bill  was  to  clarify  the  law,  while  this 
amendment  presents  the  same  question  of  construction  as  the  existing  law. 
The  law,  therefore,  would  be  neiiher  changed  nor  clarified  if  the  bill  were 
enacted  in  the  form  in  which  it  was  passed  by  the  House.  Therefore  the  busi- 
nessman who  is  deterred  from  engaging  in  cooperative  action  in  export  trade 
by  fear  and  doubt  concerning  antitrust  laws  would  be  left  in  exactly  the  same 
position  as  before. 


'  Senate  Rept.  No.  1*056,  64th  Cong.,  2d  se.'^s..  February  14,  1917.  p.  2. 
*  Annual  Rept.  of  the  l^ederal  Trade  Commission,  1916,  pp.  35,  36. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  121 

The  Senate  Committee  on  Interstate  Commerce,  in  its  report  on 
February  14,  1917,  recommended  deletion  of  the  words  "and  does  not 
restrain  the  export  trade  of  the  United  States,"  and  insertion  of  the 
clause  "and  is  not  in  restraint  of  the  export  trade  of  any  domestic 
competitor  of  such  association:  And  provided  further  *  *  *"  as 
the  law  was  finally  passed.     The  committee's  report  stated : 

As  presented  to  us,  this  section  provides  that  the  Sherman  law  shall  not  be 
construed  so  as  to  make  illegal  an  association  entered  into  for  the  sole  purpose 
of  engaging  in  export  trade,  and  actively  engaged  solely  in  export  trade  or  any 
agreement  made  or  act  done  in  the  course  of  export  trade  by  such  association. 
This  section  then  provides  that  "these  associations  or  agents  shall  not  be  in 
restraint  of  trade  within  the  United  States,  and  shall  not  restrain  the  export 
trade  of  the  United  States."  Of  course,  we  do  not  want  to  restrain  trade  within 
the  United  States  as  the  first  clause  of  the  language  quoted  provides. 

Reduced  to  its  final  analysis,  this  section  attempts  to  give  the  right  to  enter 
into  associations,  make  agreements,  and  do  acts  in  restraint  of  export  trade, 
while  the  second  clause  quoted  takes  away  this  right.  To  avoid  the  effect  of 
the  last  clause,  and  at  the  same  time  to  secure  the  purpose  of  this  act  in  the 
interests  of  our  foreign  trade,  the  committee  suggests  the  striking  out  of  the 
last  clause  and  inserting  after  the  words  "United  States"  on  line  19,  page  2, 
the  amendment  as  written  above.  By  this  change  the  committee  aims  to  place 
three  limitations  upon  these  associations,  their  acts  and  agreements : 

(«)  The  authority  hereby  conferred  should  not  result  in  the  restraint  of 
trade  within  the  United  States  which  is  clearly  prohibited  by  the  Sherman  law. 

(&)  While  the  purpose  of  the  bill  is  to  increase  our  foreign  trade,  it  should 
not  result  in  destroying  the  business  of  other  companies,  associatious,  or  indi- 
viduals who  may  be  engaged  in  the  foreign  trade.  The  purpose  is  to  increase 
and  improve  this  trade,  not  to  injure  it. 

(c)  While  we  realize  that  any  sales  in  foreign  commerce  may  incidentally 
and  temporarily  result  in  the  increase  in  prices  of  the  same  articles  to  home 
consumers,  these  associations  ought  not  to  be  permitted  to  so  conduct  their 
affairs  as  to  artificially  or  intentionally  and  unduly  enhance  prices  of  the  com- 
modities in  which  they  are  dealing  to  the  home  consumer." 

Section  3  of  the  act  states  that  nothing  in  the  Clayton  Act — 

shall  be  construed  to  forbid  the  acquisition  or  ownership  by  any  corporation 
of  the  whole  or  any  part  of  the  stock  or  other  capital  of  any  corporation  or- 
ganized solely  for  the  purpose  of  engaging  in  export  trade,  and  actually  engaged 
solely  in  such  export  trade,  unless  the  effect  of  such  acquisition  or  ownership 
may  be  to  restrain  trade  or  substantially  lessen  competition  within  the  United 
States. 

Section  4  provides  that  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act  shall 
be  construed  as — 

extending  to  unfair  methods  of  competition  used  in  export  trade  against  com- 
petitors engaged  in  export  trade,  even  though  the  acts  constituting  such  unfair 
methods  are  done  without  the  territorial  jurisdiction  of  the  United  States. 

Section  4  cases  have  been  brought  under  section  5  of  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission  Act,  as  extended  by  section  4  of  the  Export  Trade 
Act,  and  have  not  involved  operation  of  the  Webb  law  associations.^" 

Section  5  provides  for  the  filing  of  papers  with  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission,  including  copies  of  the  organization  papers,  a  first  re- 
port "  setting  forth  the  location  of  its  offices  or  places  of  business  and 
the  names  and  addresses  of  all  its  officers  and  of  all  its  stockholders  or 
members;  an  annual  report ^2;  and  also — 

such  information  as  the  Commission  may  require  as  to  its  organization,  business, 
conduct,  practices,  management,  and  i-elation  to  other  associations,  corporations, 
partnerships,  and  individuals. 


'Senate   Rept.  No.  1056,  64th  Cong.,  2d  seSs.,  February  14,  1917,  pp.  2,  3. 
'"Docket  Nos.  274,  792,  820,  1044,  1203,   1216,  1238,  1276,  1481,  1878,  1969,  2484. 
"  See  exhibit  4  herewith. 
^'  See  exhibit  5  herewith. 


122  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  bill  as  first  drafted  provided  for  the  filinsr  of  "all  contracts, 
agreements,  and  understandings  had  with  any  foreign  or  domestic 
association  in  regard  to  the  conduct  of  or  practices  in  foreign  trade." 
This  was  deleted  and  the  clause  quoted  above  as  to  "such  information 
as  the  Commission  may  require"  was  substituted  therefor. 

Section  5  provides  further  for  procedure  by  the  Commission  when- 
ever it  shall  have  reason  to  believe  that  the  law  has  been  violated. 
The  Commission  shall  summon  the  association,  its  oflScers,  and  agents 
to  appear  before  it,  and  thereafter  conduct  an  investigation  into  the 
alleged  violations  of  law.  Upon  investigation,  if  it  shall  conclude 
that  the  law  has  been  violated,  it  may  make  to  such  association  rec- 
ommendations for  the  readjustment  of  its  business,  in  order  that  it 
may  thereafter  maintain  its  organization  and  management  and  con- 
duct its  business  in  accordance  with  law.  If  the  association  fails  to 
comply  with  the  recommendations,  the  Commission  shall  refer  its 
findings  and  recommendations  to  the  Attorney  General  of  the  United 
States  for  such  action  thereon  as  he  may  deem  proper.  For  the 
purpose  of  enforcing  these  provisionSj  the  Commission  has  all  the 
powers,  so  far  as  applicable,  given  to  it  in  the  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission Act. 

Under  section  5,  the  Commission  has  required  reports  and  data ;  it 
has  made  field  calls  at  association  offices;  and  it  has  conducted  a 
number  of  inquiries  into  the  operation  of  the  Webb  law  groups.  In- 
formal advice  has  been  g"  /en  on  numerous  questions.  The  only 
formal  summons  and  recom  lendations  issued  are  those  in  the  case  of 
the  Pacific  Forest  Industries,  on  January  27,  1940,  which  will  be 
hereinafter  discussed. 


ADMINISTRATION  OF  THE  LAW 

1918-2  7 THE  EXPORT  TRADE  DIVISION FOREIGN   TRADE   SERIES  NO.    1    IN 

1919 — PROPOSED  AMENDMENT  TO  THE  LAW  IN  1921 — THE  SILVER  LETTER 
IN  1924 PROPOSED  AMENDMENT  TO  PERMIT  IMPORT  COMBINES,  INTRO- 
DUCED IN    1924     (REJECTTED  IN    1928) 

The  Export  Trade  Division  was  created  within  the  Commission 
in  1918  to  handle  the  foreign-trade  work. 

In  1919  the  Commission  published  a  13-page  pamphlet  entitled 
^'Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  1 — Discussion  of  Practice  and  Procedure 
under  the  Export  Trade  Act  (Webb-Pomerene  law"  ^)  which  included 
text  of  the  law,  a  brief  discussion  of  practice,  and  a  list  of  associations 
at  that  time  filing  papers  (some  of  these  companies  were  soon  there- 
after stricken  from  the  list  because  it  was  found  that  they  were  not 
solely  engaged  in  exporting).  Some  excerpts  from  this  pamphlet 
may  be  of  interest: 

The  very  numerous  requests  for  copies  of  the  Export  Trade  Act  (Webb- 
Pomerene  law)  and  the  large  number  of  inquiries  about  it  call  for  the  publica- 
tion of  a  separate  pamphlet  by  this  Commission  for  the  information  of  those 
desiring  to  cooperate  in  the  development  of  our  foreign  trade  through  associa- 
tions formed  under  that  act. 

In  several  instances  suggestions  have  been  made  as  to  modifications  of  pro- 
posed articles  of  incorporation,  already  filed,  in  order  that  these  associations 
may  clearly  come  within  the  provisions  of  the  act.  The  Commission  is  author- 
ized by  this  law  to  make  recommendations  as  to  how  export  associations  may 
conform  their  business  to  the  law,  and,  within  its  powers,  it  proposes  to  advance 
step  by  step  in  aid  of  the  export  needs  of  the  country.  It  desires  to  constantly 
work  in  cooperation  with  those  who  form  export  associations  and  also  with 
those  who  may  consider  themselves  or  the  public  in  any  way  injuriously  affected 
by  the  methods  and  practices  of  such  associations. 

Where  doubt  exists  as  to  whether  a  given  method  or  practice  is  proper  or  not, 
it  would  seem  advisable  that  the  matter  be  voluntarily  presented  to  the  Com- 
mission in  the  early  stages,  without  awaiting  its  later  discovery  and  possible 
correction.  The  second  paragraph  of  section  5  of  the  Webb  Act  describes  the 
few  formalities  as  to  such  procedure. 

«  *  *  *  «  *  • 

Numerous  requests  have  been  received  by  the  Commission  for  rulings  upon  the 
construction  of  the  Export  Trade  Act.  It  has  been  deemed  inadvisable  to  attempt 
at  this  time  to  officially  construe  any  of  the  provisions  of  the  law  upon  informal 
applications.  This  is  especially  true,  as  the  penalty  for  the  violation  of  section  5 
of  the  act  is  enforcible  by  the  district  attorneys  of  the  United  States  under  the 
direction  of  the  Attorney  General,  and  not  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission, 
and  the  enforcement  of  the  Sherman  law  is  a  duty  of  the  Federal  courts  upon 
proceedings  instituted  by  the  Department  of  Justice. 

It  is  exceedingly  important  that  export  associations  in  process  of  formation 
should  give  careful  consideration  to  the  wording  of  sections  2  and  3  of  the  Ex- 
port Trade  Act.  As  to  the  statements  which  have  been  filed  with  the  Export  Trade 
Division  under  section  5  of  this  act,  it  has  been  noted  that  practically  every  cor- 
poration formed  has  been  organized  for  the  transaction  of  some  business  other 
than  that  of  solely  engaging  in  exporting  from  the  United  States  to  foreign 
nations  as  defined  in  the  act. 


*  This  pampblet  la  out  of  print,  but  one  copy  is  herewith  transmitted  as  exhibit  6. 

123 


224  OONCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Most  of  the  articles  of  association  filed  have  also  contemplated  the  transaction 
of  business  other  than  that  of  exporting  to  foreign  nations.  It  is  apparent  under 
the  law  that  the  provisions  of  the  Sherman  law  and  section  1  of  the  Clayton  law 
remain  applicable  as  to  all  combinations  which  are  not  organized  solely  for  the 
business  of  exporting  to  foreign  nations.  The  business  of  exporting  to  the  Phil- 
ippine Islands,  to  Puerto  Rico,  or  to  Hawaii  seems  clearly  to  be  domestic  and  not 
foreign  trade,  and  the  provisions  of  the  Sherman  law  and  section  7  of  the  Clayton 
law  seem  to  continue  in  force  as  to  any  association  or  export  corporation  which 
engages  in  such  business. 

One  of  the  difficulties  which  exporting  houses  seem  to  find  with  the  law  is  that 
export  companies  usually  both  export  and  import,  while  the  law  provides  that  its 
protection  is  given  to  associations  entered  into  for  the  sole  purpose  of  engaging 
in  export  trade  and  actually  engaged  solely  in  such  export  trade. 

Due  to  the  facts  that  the  business  of  the  country  is  devoting  its  thought  to  war 
production,  and  that  there  is  a  lack  of  shipping  facilities,  general  plans  for  cooper- 
ation in  export  trade  are  probably  now  in  suspense  or  only  in  a  formative  state. 
This  is  indicated  by  the  very  small  number  of  association  papers  which  have  been 
filed  with  the  Commission  since  the  passage  of  the  act  on  April  10,  1918. 
******* 

The  Commission  is  keeping  informed  as  to  the  export  needs  of  the  country  in 
order  to  be  of  assistance  so  that  American  producers  may  cooperate  to  the  fullest 
extent  in  export  fields,  without  injuriously  affecting  domestic  commerce,  or  the 
foreign  commerce  of  those  exporters  who  are  associated  with  export-trade  asso- 
ciations. 

Progress  has  been  made  in  the  preparation  of  an  additional  report  on  foreign- 
trade  conditions  under  section  6,  clause  H,  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  act, 
reading  as  follows : 

Sec.  6.  That  the  Commission  shall  also  have  power — 

(h)  To  investigate,  from  time  to  time,  trade  conditions  in  and  with  foreign 
countries  where  associations,  combinations,  or  practices  of  manufacturers,  mer- 
chants, or  traders,  or  other  conditions,  may  affect  the  foreign  trade  of  the  United 
States,  and  to  report  to  Congress  thereon,  with  such  recommendations  as  it  deems 
advisable. 

The  world-wide  dislocation  of  trade  and  industry  incident  to  the  war  is  creating 
new  conditions  which  may  vitally  affect  American  business  in  the  futuro.  The 
Commission  is  closely  following  new  developments  in  international  trade,  as  they 
arise,  with  a  view  to  ascertaining  the  bearing  they  may  have  on  the  foreign  trade 
of  the  United  States. 

In  1921  a  bill  was  offered  in  Congress  which  would  have  amended 
the  law.2    The  text  was  as  follows : 

To  amend  an  Act  entitled  "An  Act  to  promote  export  trade,  and  for  other  pur- 
poses," approved  April  10,  1918. 

Be  it  enacted  by  the  Senate  and  House  of  Representatives  of  the  United  States 
of  America  in  Congress  assembled,  That  the  Act  entitled  "An  Act  to  promote  exiwrt 
trade,  and  for  other  purposes,"  approved  April  10,  1918,  be,  and  the  same  is  hereby, 
amended  by  adding  at  the  end  of  section  5  of  said  Act  the  following :  "An  associa- 
tion shall  be  deemed  to  be  engaged  in  export  trade  for  the  purpose  of  this  Act  if  it 
shall  promote  agreements  among  its  members  as  to  the  prices  and  terms  which 
shall  govern  the  sale  of  their  products  to.  foreign  customers,  engage  in  trade  pro- 
motion abroad,  transmit  to  its  members  inquiries  or  orders  received  from  foreign 
customers  for  the  purchase  of  their  products,  agree  as  to  terms  of  credit  and  as  to 
the  allowance  or  refusal  of  credit  or  of  sales  to  foreign  customers,  and  generally 
promote  such  agreements  and  understandings  among  its  members  as  are  necessary 
to  protect  them  from  hurtful  combinations  and  practices  of  foreign  competitors 
or  customers." 

This  bill  was  referred  to  the  Senate  Committee  on  Interstate  Com- 
merce, but  was  never  acted  upon  by  the  Senate, 

A  history  of  Webb-Pomerene  law  operation  would  be  incomplete 
without  mention  of  the  Silver  letter  because  this  announced  a  change 
in  the  operation  of  some  of  the  export  groups.  During  the  first  years 
of  operation,  the  associations  formed  were  selling  agencies,  actually 

'  S.  2683,  67th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  introduced  by  Senator  Fletcher,  November  4,  1921. 


OONCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  125 

taking  orders  and  negotiating  export  sales  for  their  members.  After 
issuance  of  the  Silver  letter,  some  associations  were  formed  under 
which  the  member  companies  retained  their  own  sales  offices  and 
agents  under  association  direction.  This  new  type  of  organization 
was  attractive  to  a  group  in  which  the  members  had  already  estab- 
lished export  departments  or  companies  and  did  not  wish  to  abolish 
them  and  substitute  a  central  sales  bureau. 

On  November  22,  1923,  the  silver  producers  addressed  an  inquiry 
to  the  Secretary  of  Conunerce  presenting  a  number  of  hypothetical 
questions.  This  was  referred  to  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  and 
on  July  31,  1924,  the  Commission  replied  to  the  silver  producers  in  a 
letter  which  was  published  in  a  news  release  dated  August  6, 1924 : 

Fedebat.  Trade  Commission 

washington 

For  release  in  morning  newspapers  of  Wednesday,  August  6,  1924. 

The  Federal  Trade  Commission  today  published  the  following  letter  to  a 
committee  of  silver  producers  of  the  United  States  in  which  the  Commission 
interprets  the  Webb-Pomerene  Export  Trade  Act  in  response  to  certain  queries 
propounded  by  the  silver  producers.  The  questions  of  the  silver  producers  were 
prompted  by  the  contemplated  formation  by  them  of  an  export  association. 
Commissioners  Thompson  and  Nugent  are  not  in  accordiWith  the  Commission's 
action. 

July  31,  1924. 

My  Deab  Mb.  Kkt.t-Ry  :  In  the  Federal  Trade  Commission's  letter  of  April  18, 
1924,  a  committee  of  silver  producers  of  the  United  States  was  informed  that 
the  Commission  by  reason  of  a  then  existing  vacancy  in  its  membership  was 
unable  to  act  by  a  majority  upon  certain  questions  propounded  by  the  silver 
producers'  committee  in  their  communication  of  November  22,  1923,  to  the  Secre- 
tary of  Commerce  in  regard  to  the  proposed  formation  of  an  association  under 
the  Export  Trade  Act  (Webb-Pomerene  Act)  and  the  rights  and  powers  of  such 
an  association.  As  the  administration  of  this  act  is  lodged  with  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission,  the  committee's  communication  was  referred  here  by  the 
Secretary  of  Commerce  on  December  13,  1923. 

The  vacancy  on  the  Commission  having  been  filled,  and  representations  having 
recently  been  made  to  the  Commission  from  which  it  appears  that  an  emergency 
situation  exists  in  the  industry  by  x-eason  of  the  meeting  of  the  American  Silver 
Producers  Association  to  be  held  in  Salt  Lake  City  on  August  6  next,  and  the 
desire  of  that  association  and  of  Senators  who  are  members  of  the  Senate 
Gold  and  Silver  Commission,  who  will  attend  this  meeting,  that  the  decision  of 
the  Federal  Trade  Commission  upon  the  queries  submitted  by  the  silver  producers 
be  available  prior  to  the  meeting,  it  is  the  view  of  the  members  of  the  Commission 
now  sitting,  which  members  constitute  a  majority,  that  it  is  not  only  proper  but 
highly  desirable  that  the  Commission  act  in  this  matter. 

Therefore,  in  view  of  an  emergency  situation  a  majority  of  the  Commission, 
consisting  of  Commissioners  Van  Fleet,  Gaskill,  and  Hunt,  have  acted  and  have 
agreed  upon  a  reply  to  the  communication  of  November  22,  1923,  from  the  Com- 
mittee of  Silver  Producers  of  the  United  States.  Commissioners  Thompson  and 
Nugent,  who  are  absent  from  the  city  at  this  time,  have  heretofore  considered 
the  matter  and  do  not  agree  with  the  majority.  The  reply  of  the  majority 
follows : 

It  seems  to  be  open  under  the  terms  of  the  act,  for  those  who  desire  to  form 
an  association  under  its  provisions,  to  file  with  the  Federal  Trade  Commission 
the  declarations  referred  to  in  section  5  of  the  Webb-Pomerene  Act.  The  prelimi 
nary  assent  of  the  Commission  to  export  association  existence  and  activity  under 
the  act  is  not  required.  Effort  was  made  at  the  time  the  act  was  passed  to 
include  in  it  the  following  amendment : 

"Before  any  association  shall  engage  in  business  under  this  act  it  shall 
secure  from  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  a  permit  to  engage  in  such  business, 
and  said  Commission  is  authorized  to  issue  such  i)ermits  and  may,  in  its  dis- 
cretion, refuse  a  permit  to  any/ association,  and  may,  after  hearing,  cancel  any 
permit  issued." 


126  OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  omission  of  this  amendment,  together  with  the  clear  import  of  the  act 
as  passed,  indicates  that  the  action  of  the  Commission  toward  export  associa- 
tions is  corrective  of  action  taken  rather  than  a  limitation  upon  the  entry  into 
action. 

The  Federal  Trade  Commission  is,  however,  given  control  over  the  action 
of  export  trade  associations,  as  will  appear  by  section  5  of  the  act. 

"Se3c.  5.  Whenever  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  shall  have  reason  to 
believe  that  an  association  or  any  agreement  made  or  act  done  by  such  associa- 
tion is  in  restraint  of  trade  within  the  United  States,  or  in  restraint  of  the 
export  trade  of  any  domestic  competitor  of  such  association,  or  that  an  asso- 
ciation either  in  the  United  States  or  elsewhere  has  entered  into  any  agree- 
ment, understanding,  or  conspiracy,  or  done  any  act  which  artificially  or  inten- 
tionally enhances  or  depresses  prices  within  the  United  States  of  commodities 
of  the  class  exported  by  such  association,  or  which  substantially  lessens  com- 
petition within  the  United  States  or  otherwise  restrains  trade  therein,  it  shall 
summon  sikch  association,  its  oflScers,  and  agents  to  appear  before  it,  and 
thereafter  conduct  an  investigation  into  the  alleged  violations  of  law.  Upon 
investigation,  if  it  shall  conclude  that  the  law  has  been  violated,  it  may  make 
to  such  association  recommendations  for  the  readjustment  of  its  business,  in 
order  that  it  may  thereafter  maintain  its  organization  and  management  and 
conduct  its  1  business  in  accordance  with  law.  If  such  association  fails  to  com- 
ply with  the  recommendations  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  said  Commis- 
sion shall  refer  its  findings  and  recommendations  to  the  Attorney  General  of 
the  United  States  for  such  action  thereon  as  he  may  deem  proper." 

It  is  entirely  proper,  therefore,  that  the  Commission  should,  when  called  upon 
in  advance  of  the  formation  of  an  export  trade  association,  indicate  that  pro- 
posed lines  of  conduct  would  in  its  opinion,  when  carried  int<\ actual  operation, 
invite  the  corrective  attention  of  the  Commission.  But  the  \>i;,inmission  cannot 
assume  the  results  of  an  indicated  course  of  conduct.  As  appears  from  the 
statute  itself,  the  test  of  legality  lies  in  result  in  most  instances  rather  than 
in  the  form  or  method  pursued.  The  Commission  cannot  always  make  a  precise 
statement  under  these  circumstances. 

You  will  understand,  therefore,  that  any  preliminary  expression  is  advisory 
only  and  that  the  committee  which  you  represent  is  tlierebj'  in  no  way  pre- 
cluded from  asserting  any  method  of  coordinate  action  which  you  believe  to  be 
within  the  intent  and  spirit  of  the  act.  If  your  views  should  differ  from  those 
of  the  Commission  and  the  results  accomplished  should  in  its  judgment  fall 
within  the  scope  of  the  prohibitions  of  the  act,  it  would  become  the  duty  of  the 
Commission  to  proceed  to  a  determination  of  the  issues  involved  in  the  manner 
provided  by  the  act  itself. 

You  ask : 

"1.  Do  provisions  of  the  Webb-Pomerene  Act  limit  persons  (natural  or  cor- 
porate) who  may  enter  into  such  an  association,  to  citizens  of  the  United  States 
or  corporations  formed  under  the  laws  of  the  United  States  or  some  State 
thereof?" 

It  seems  that  this  question  should  be  answered  in  the  affirmative,  with  pos- 
sibly certain  explanations.  The  Congress  of  the  United  States  legislates  with 
reference  to  the  citizens  of  the  United  States  and  its  sovereignty.  Within  the 
sovereignty  of  the  United  States  are  many  who  are  not  its  citizens,  but  who  are 
governed  by  its  laws.  The  laws  of  the  United  States,  therefore,  are  applicable 
to  citizens  of  the  United  States,  to  those  who  are  not  citizens  of  the  United 
States  but  are  residents  thereof,  and  to  corporations  formed  under  the  laws  of 
the  United  States  or  of  some  State  within  the  United  States. 

It  might  be  added  that  there  is  nothing  in  the  act  which  prevents  an  asso- 
ciation formed  under  it  from  entering  into  any  cooperative  relationship  with 
a  foreign  corporation  for  the  sole  purpose  of  operation  in  a  foreign  market. 
The  only  test  of  legality  in  such  an  arrangement  would  be  the  effect  upon 
domestic  conditions  within  the  United  States. 

You  ask : 

"2.  Is  the  export  product  that  may  be  disposed  of  by  such  an  association 
limited  to  productions  originating  in  and  exported  directly  from  ports  of  the 
United  States,  or  does  it  also  include  products  originating  outside  the  United 
States,  but  thereafter  imported  into  the  United  States  and  from  thence  exported 
to  foreign  markets  directly  from  ports  of  the  United  States?" 

The  act  is  silent  on  this  subject.  In  the  absence  of  an  indication  to  the  con- 
trary expressed  in  the  act,  the  word  "export"  is  assumed  -to  include  only  domes- 
tic products  and  not  the  objects  of  import  which  form  the  basis  of  a  subsequent 
export  movement. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  127 

"2-a.  Is  the  export  product  that  may  be  disposed  of  by  such  an  association 
limited  to  a  product  which  is  shipped  from  the  United  States,  or  may  it  also 
embrace  a  product  of  a  member  of  the  association  produced  outside  of  the 
United  States,  and  shipped  direct  to  a  foreign  port,  without  first  entering  the 
United  States?" 

It  is  difficult  to  see  how  shipment  from  a  foreign-  port  to  a  foreign  port 
could  be  regarded  as  export  from  the  United  States.  The  first  impression  would 
be  tliat  such  conduct  would  not  come  within  the  scope  of  thei  act. 

You  ask : 

"3.  Can  a  valid  trade  agreement  be  entered  into  between  such  export  asso- 
ciation (c)  between  nationals  engaged  in  the  production  and  exporting  of 
commodities  of  commerce  outside  the  Uittfced  States,  but  whose  product  would 
reach  the  same  foreign  marliet  as  the  pr(5chict  of  the  exi>ort  association  export- 
ing such  product  direct  from  the  United  States;  and  (&)  nonnationals  engaged 
in  the  production  and  exporting  of  commodities  outside  the  United  States,  but 
whose  product  would  reach  the  same  foreign  market  as  the  product  of  the 
export  association  exporting  such  product  direct  from  the  United  States?" 

The  purpose  of  the  act  seems  to  have  been  to  provide  a  method  for  elimi- 
nating competition  in  foreign  markets  among  domestic  producers.  As  stated 
above,  tiiere  seems  to  be  no  reason  why  a  Webb-Pomerene  association  comjwsed 
of  nationals  or  residents  of  the  United  States  and  actually  exporting  from  the 
United  States,  might  not  adopt  a  trade  arrangement  with  nonnationals  reaching 
the  same  market,  providing  this  market  was  not  the  domestic  market  of  the 
United  States  and  the  action  of  this  organization  did  not  reflect  unlawfully 
upon  domestic  conditions.  It  does  not  seem,  however,  that  nationals  and 
nonnationals  who  are  also  nonresidents,  might  unite  within  the  Webb-Pomerene 
association  itself. 

You  ask : 

"4.  Must  an  export  association  under  the  act  perform  all  the  operations 
of  selling  its  members'  product  to  the  foreign  buyer,  or  does  the  word  'com- 
merce' in  the  act  mean  that  an  exjMJrt  association  complies  with  the  act  if 
it  is  solely  engaged  in  allotting  export  orders  among  its  members,  or  in  fixing 
the  prices  at  which  its  individual  members  shall  sell  any  export  trade,  or  in 
performing  any  one  or  moi'e  of  the  other  operations  comprised  in  the  complete 
chain  of  operations  that  constitute  selling  and  export  trade  under  the  general 
trade  agreement  that  deals  solely  with  export  trade  and  as  filed  with  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission,  in  accordance  with  the  terms  of  the  act?" 

The  act  does  not  require  that  the  association  shall  perform  all  the  operations 
of  selling  its  members'  product  to  a  foreign  buyer.  The  limitation  upon  the 
methods  of  operation  is  to  be  found  in  the  words:  "in  the  course  of  export." 
The  Commission  has  recently  passed  upon  the  conduct  of  an  association  which 
does  not  itself  export,  but  which  performs  a  price-fixing  function  and  an  alloca- 
tion of  business,  and  sells  at  the  wharf  to  others  than  the  association,  who 
conduct  the  export  movement  from  that  point.  The  position  which  the  Com- 
mission takes  is  that  the  consummation  of  a  sale  within  the  United  States 
if  the  product  sold  is  intended  for  and  actually  is  marked  for  and  enters  into 
export  trade,  is  in  the  course  of  export  within  the  meaning  of  the  act.  I'ti 
would  seem,  therefore,  that  an  association  may  without  necessarily  involving 
conflict  with  the  act,  engage  in  allotting  export  orders  among  its  members  and 
in  fixing  prices  at  which  the  individual  members  shall  sell  in  export  trade. 

The  law  provides  two  tests :  One,  that  the  conduct  shall  be  in  export  or  in 
the  course  of  export.  The  second,  that  the  conduct  shall  not  be  in  restraint  of 
trade  within  the  United  States,  shall  not  restrain  the  export  trade  of  any 
domestic  comi)etitor,  and  shall  not  artificially  enhance  prices  or  lessen  compe- 
tition within  the  United  States,  or  otherwise  restrain  trade  therein.  The 
application  of  the  second  group  of  tests,  of  course,  is  dependent  upon  the  results 
of  conduct  which  cannot  be  forecast,  at  least  by  the  Commission. 

It  may  be  noted  that  the  pajjcrs  filed  by  several  associations  show  that  the 
actual   export  and   sale   in   foreign   markets  is  conducted   by   the   individual 
members. 
You  ask : 

"5.  Does  the  prohibition  of  the  above  act  against  affecting  domestic  commerce, 
extend  to  and  include  a  consequential  rise  in  price  in  the  domestic  markeit 
through  the  better  organized  control  of  the  foreign  markets  and  the  broadening 
of  export  trade ;  or  is  such  prohibition  limited  to  acts  which  intentionally  or 
directly  are  committed  to  advance  the  domestic  price  or  restrain  trade  through 
an  operation  conducted  merely  in  the  guise  of  an  export  association?" 


228  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

It  was  not  within  the  purview  of  this  act  that  the  operations  of  a  Webb- 
Pomerene  association  should  become  a  device  for  betterment  of  a  domestic 
market.  Its  sole  purpose  was  the  lessening  of  competition  between  domestic 
exporters  in  the  foreign  markets.  It  is  exceedingly  difficult  to  distinguish 
between  a  betterment  of  the  domestic  market  expressed  in  a  rising  domestic 
price  which  is  the  result  of  the  proper  coordination  of  export  to  domestic  con- 
sumption and  a  similar  movement  directed  to  the  domestic  market  in  which 
this  result  is  directly  and  primarily  intended  through  an  adjustment  of  com- 
petitive relations  in  a  foreign  market.  The  law  prohibits  monopolistic  effort 
of  interference  with  competition  by  concerted  action  in  the  guise  of  a  produc- 
tion of  benefit  to  the  public.  It  has  been  repeatedly  stated  that  a  beneficent 
purpose  will  not  legalize  conduct  otherwise  unlawful.  The  mere  fact  that  there 
was  a  rising  price  in  the  domestic  market  would  not  be  a  controlling  element. 
It  is  perfectly  apparent  that  the  proper  adjustment  of  distribution  may  result 
in  an  increase  in  price  in-  a  glutted  market  and  a  decrease  in  price  in  one  which 
is  insuflaciently  supplied.  Manifestly  the  arrangement  must  be  devoid  of  any 
concerted  curtailment  of  production  or  withdrawal  from  the  domestic  market 
■of  any  part  of  its  normal  supply.  It  is  well  understood  that  an  incidental  or 
inconsequential  effect  upon  domestic  prices  is  not  unlawful.  If  a  merely  con- 
sequential rise  in  price  should  bar  American  exporters  from  using  this  statute, 
the  statute  might  become  a  nullity.  The  statute  provides  for  a  lawful  course 
of  procedure,  and  if  this  procedure  is  followed  and  the  statute  complied  with, 
merely  indirect  or  consequential  results  cannot  be  held  to  be  against  the  law. 
It  is  well  settled,  under  the  Shermkn  Act,  that  a  contract  which  "only  inciden- 
tally or  indirectly  restricts  competition  is  not  denounced  by  the  act." 

By  direction  of  the  Commission : 

Vebnon  W.  Van  Fleet, 

Acting  Ohadrman. 
Mr.  C.  F.  Kelley, 

Silver  ProeLucers'  Committee, 

Room  1801,  25  Broadway,  New  York  City. 

In  1924  a  bill  was  introduced  in  the  Senate  ^  that  would  have 
permitted  the  formation  of  import  combines  to  engage  in  cooper- 
ative purchasing  of  "raw  commodities  which  are  produced  prin- 
cipally in  foreign  countries."  The  Webb-Pomerene  law  was  not 
mentioned,  but  administration  was  to  be  given  to  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission.  The  same  bill  was  introduced  by  Senator  Capper 
in  1925,*  In  December  1925  a  House  resolution  introduced  by 
Congressman  Tilson  ^  recommended  an  investigation  by  the  House 
Committee  on  Interstate  and  Foreign  Commerce,  as  to  the  "means 
and  methods  of  the  control  of  production  and  exportation  of  crude 
rubber,  coffee,  silk,  nitrates,  potash,  quinine,  iodine,  tin,  sisal,  quick- 
silver, and  other  important  raw  materials ;"  this  was  favorably  rec- 
ommended by  the  House  Committee  on  Rules.^  Hearings  on  the 
resolution  were  conducted  by  the  House  Committee  on  Interstate 
and  Foreign  Commerce  in  January  1926.^  The  committee's  prelimi- 
nary report  was  issued  in  March  1926.^ 

As  a  result  of  this  inquiry^  two  bills  were  introduced  in  Congress  in 
1928,^  which  would  have  amended  the  Webb-Pomerene  law  to  permit 

»  S.  2843,  68th  Cong.,  1st  sess..  Introduced  by  Senator  Capper  on  March  14,  1924,  and 
referred  to  the  Committee  on  Commerce. 

*  S.  1T99,  69th  Cong.,  Ist  sess.,  introduced  by  Senator  Capper  on  December  17,  1925,  and 
referred  to  the  Committee  on  Commerce. 

»  H.  Res.  58,  69th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  Introduced  by  Congressman  Tilson,  December  18,  1925, 
referred  to  the  Committee  on  Rules. 

*  Rept.  No.  24,  House  of  Representatives,  69th  Cong^  1st  sess.,  December  19,  1925,  1  p. 

'  Hearings  before  the  Committee  on  Interstate  and  Foreign  Commerce,  House  of  Repre- 
sentatives, 69th  Cong.,  Ist  sess.,  on  H.  Res.  59,  January  6,  7,  8,  11,  12,  13,  14,  15,  18,  19, 
and  22,  1926,  published  in  1926,  373  pp. 

*  Rept.  No.  555,  House  of  Representatives,  69th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  March  13,  1926,  23  pp. 
0  S.   2312,  70th  Cong.,  1st   sess.,  introduced  by   Senator  Jones,  January  9,   1928,   and 

referred  to  the  Senate  Committee  on  Commerce ;  and  H.  R.  8927,  70th  Cong.,  1st  sess., 
introduced  by  Congressman  Newton  on  the  same  date,  referred  to  the  House  Committee  on 
the  Judiciary. 


(X)NCENTRATION  OF  ElOONOMIO  POWER  129 

combines  for  importation  of  crude  rubber,  potash,  sisal,  or  "other  raw 
materials,  or  products  of  nature  in  a  crude  or  unfinished  state  which 
are  certified  by  the  Secretary  of  Commerce  to  be  of  a  character  not 
made,  produced,  or  grown  in  substantial  quantities  within  the  United 
States,  or  to  be  controlled  by  any  foreign  government,  combination,  or 
monopoly."  Such  import  combines  would  have  been  required  to  file 
papers  with  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  and  to  operate  under  the 
Commission's  supervision  on  terms  similar  to  those  in  effect  for  export 
combines.  The  Export  Trade  Act  was  completely  redrafted  in  the 
bill,  to  include  the  new  provisions.  Hearings  were  held  on  H.  R.  8927 
by  the  House  Committee  on  the  Judiciary  in  January  1928.^°  The 
committee  submitted  a  report  in  February  1928  ^^  to  the  effect — 

that  the  bill  do  not  pass  at  this  time.  The  sponsors  of  the  bill  -should  give  the 
problem  further  study  so  as  to  write  into  the  law  the  conditions  of  resale  of 
such  material,  specifying  such  factors  and  charges  which  may  properly  be  added 
to  the  original  cost  of  the  raw  material  involved. 

An  amended  bill  was  then  submitted  by  Congressman  Newton,  still 
numbered  H.  R.  8927,  and  in  March  1928  a  House  resolution  ^^  brought 
the  bill  up  for  debate.  The  Committee  on  Rules  approved  the  resolu- 
tion." The  bill  was  debated  in  the  House  in  April  1928.^*  On  April 
4,  however,  the  day  before  the  debates  began,  the  British  Prime  Min- 
ister stated  in  the  House  of  Commons  that  the  British  rubber  restric- 
tions would  be  removed  on  November  1  of  that  year.  This  eliminated 
one  of  the  principal  reasons  for  passage  of  the  bill,  since  without 
restriction  the  price  of  crude  rubber  would  be  lowered.  The  bill  was 
therefore  rejected  by  the  House  on  April  6,  1928;  it  was  not  acted 
upon  in  the  Senate. 

llt2"-40 — THE  EXPORT   TRADE  SECTION — FOREIGN  TRADE  SERIES  NO.   2,  1935 — 
PACIFIC  FOREST  INDUSTRIES,   RECOMMENDATIONS,  1940 

On  July  1,  1927,  the  Export  Trade  Division  became  the  Export 
Trade  Section  under  the  chief  counsel's  office  of  the  Commission.^^ 

In  October  1935  the  Commission  issued  a  23-page  pamphlet  en- 
titled "Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  2 — Practice  and  Procedure  Under 
the  Export  Trade  Act  (Webb-Pomerene  law)"  ^*  which  discussed  pur- 
pose of  tlie  law,  provisions  of  the  act,  filing  of  papers  with  the  Com- 
mission, Webb  law  organization  and  operation,  advantages  obtained 
by  Webb  law  groups,  products  exported,  and  a  list  of  associations 
formed  during  tlie  period  1918-35.  This  pamphlet  is  still  in  active 
use  by  associations  organizing  and  operating  under  the  law;  the  text 
is  available,  and  need  not  be  repeated  here. 

On  January  27,  1940,  the  Commission  issued  recommendations  for 
the  readjustment  of  tlie  business  of  Pacific  Forest  Industries,  an 
export  trade  association,  under  section  5  of  the  act.  A  hearing  was 
lield  on  this  case  on  September  12,  1939,  investigation  was  made,  briefs 

'"  Hearings  before  the  Committee  on  the  Judiciary,  House  of  Representatives,  70th 
Conp.,  1st  sess.,  on  H.  R.  8927.  January  19,  1928,  serial  3.  published  in  1928. 

"  Rept.  No.  689  House  of  Representatives,  70th  Cong.,  1st  sess..  presented  by  Congr  ss- 
"hian   Dyer  from  the  Committee  on  the  Judiciary.  February  15,  1928,  9  pp. 

"  H.  Res.  140.  70th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  introduced  bv  Congressman  Michener,  March  17, 
1928. 

13  Rept.  No.  1058,  House  of  Representatives,  70th  Cong.,   1st  sess.,  March  27,  1928. 

^*  Congressional  Record,  debates  on  April  5  and  G,  1928,  the  bill  rejected  on  April  6,  and 
further  speeches   and  data  presented  with  the  issues  of  April  9,  12,  and  19,   1928. 

'^  News  release  issued  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  May  31,  1927. 

"  See  exhibit  7  herewith 


230  OONCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

and  other  data  were  filed.    This  was  the  first  formal  action  taken 
under  section  5  of  the  law.    Text  of  the  recommendation  follows : 

UNITED  STATES  OF  AMERICA  BEFORE  FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION 

At  a  regular  session  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  held  at  its  office  in  the 
city  of  Washington,  D.  C,  on  the  27th  day  of  January,  A.  D.  1940 

Commissioners:  Ewin  L.  Davis,  Chairman;  Garland  S.  Ferguson;  Charles  K. 
March ;  William  A.  Ayres ;  Robert  E.  Freer.    Ap.  1 13889 

RECOMMENDATIONS  FOR  THE  READJUSTMENT  OF  THE  BUSINESS 
OF  PACIFIC  FOREST  INDUSTRIES,  AN  EXPORT  TRADE  ASSOCIATION 

To :  Pacific  Forest  Industries,  a  cooperative  association  organized  under  the  laws*^ 

of  the  State  of  Washington,  with  principal  office  and  place  of  business  at 

Tacoma,  Wash.,  and  its  several  members : 

The  Federal  Trade  Commission,  having  reason  to  believe  that  Pacific  Forest 
Industries,  an  association  engaged  in  export  trade  (as  "association"  and  "export 
trade"  are  defined  in  the  act  of  Congress  known  as  the  Export  Trade  Act,  approved 
April  10,  1918),  and  certain  of  its  agreements  and  acts  were  in  restraint  of  the 
export  trade  of  domestic  competitors  of  said  association,  summoned  said  associa- 
tion, its  officers  and  agents,  to  appear  before  it  on  the  12th  day  of  September  1939 
as  provided  by  section  5  of  said  Export  Trade  Act.  Said  association  having  duly 
appeared  before  the  Commission  pursuant  to  said  summons  and  a  hearing  and 
investigation  into  the  alleged  violations  of  law  having  been  conducted  by  the 
Commission,  and  oral  and  written  statements  and  arguments  and  briefs  having 
been  presented  by  said  association,  and  the  Commission  having  concluded  upon 
such  investigation  that  the  antitrust  laws  have  been  violated  by  said  association 
in  that  said  association  and  certain  agreements  made  and  acts  done  by  it  have 
been  and  are  in  restraint  of  the  export  trade  of  its  domestic  competitors,  to  wit, 
other  American  exporters  engaged  in  purchasing,  transporting,  and  selling  Douglas 
fir  plywood  in  export  trade. 

Now,  THEREFORE,  pursuant  to  the  provisions  of  said  Export  Trade  Act  and  Ly 
virtue  of  the  authority  conferred  upon  it  by  said  act,  the  Federal  Trade  Commis- 
sion hereby  makes  to  said  Pacific  Forest  Industries  and  its  several  members  the 
following  recommendations  for  the  readjustment  of  its  business  in  order  that  it 
may  hereafter  maintain  its  organization  and  management  and  conduct  its 
business  in  accordance  with  law  : 

1.  That  Pacific  Forest  Industries  shall  not,  by  its  bylaws,  contracts  with 
members  or  associate  members,  or  otherwise,  prohibit  its  members  or 
associate  members  from  selling  plywood  directly  to  American  exporters. 

it  Section  XVI  of  the  present  bylaws  of  Pacific  Forest  Industries  provides 
that  "the  several  members  agree  to  *  ♦  *  turn  over  to  the  associa- 
tion, as  and  when  received,  all  future  orders  for  export ;  *  ♦  *.  The 
members  agree  not  to  accept  any  future  export  orders,  but  to  transmit 
and  turn  the  same  over  to  the  association."  Contracts  between  Pacific 
Forest  Industries  and  associate  member  plywood  mills  provide  that  the 
associate  member  "will  not  sell  or  offer  for  sale  directly  or  indirectly  any 
plywood  for  export,  except  through  said  association."  Said  bylaws  and 
contracts,  and  any  other  existing  bylaws,  contracts,  or  agreements  to  the 
same  effect,  should  be  rescinded  or  amended  so  as  to  permit  members  and 
associate  members  of  said  association  to  accept  and  fill  orders  for  ply- 
wood for  export  received  by  them,  respectively,  from  American  exporters 
without  reference  to  or  approval  by  the  association. 

3.  That  Pacific  Forest  Industries  shall  not  impose  any  penalties,  forfeitures, 

or  charges  upon  sales  of  plywood  by  its  members  or  associate  members 
to  American  exporters,  or  fix  or  prescribe  prices,  terms,  or  conditions  of 
sales  to  or  by  American  exporters  of  plywood  produced  by  its  members, 
or  take  any  other  action  designed  to  prevent  or  restrict  such  sales. 

4.  That  Pacific  Forest  Industries  cease  and  desist  from  advertising  in  foreign 

countries  that  it  is  the  sole  export  representative  of  the  plywood  mills 
in  the  United  States  Pacific  Northwest  and  from  making  any  similar 
advertising  claims  to  the  effect  that  United  States  Douglas  fir  plywood 
can  be  purchased  in  foreign  countries  only  through  Pacific  Forest 
Industries  or  its  agents. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13]^. 

The  term  "American  exporter"  is  defined,  for  the  purpose  of  these  recommenda- 
tions, as  a  citizen  of  the  United  States,  a  partnership  in  which  the  partner  or 
partners  owning  the  principal  beneficial  interest  is  or  are  citizens  of  the  United 
States,  or  a  corporation  domiciled  in  the  United  States  the  majority  of  the  stock 
of  which  is  owned  by  citizens  of  the  United  States,  desiring  to  purchase  plywood 
for  his,  their,  or  its  own  account  for  resale  in  export  trade. 

By  the  Commission. 

[se:al]  a.  N.  Ross,  Acting  Secretary. 

ANNUAL  REPORTS   OF  THE   COMMISSION,    1916-.39 — PUBLICITY  STATEMENTS 
ISSUED  BY  THE  COMMISSION  CONCERNING  THE  LAW 

The  Commission's  annual  reports  have  given,  each  year,  a  statement 
of  Webb  law  activities  during  that  period,  beginning  in  1915  with 
a  report  on  the  foreign-trade  inquiry  instituted  in  May  of  that  year, 
and  in  1916  a  report  on  the  bill  at  that  time  before  Congress,  con- 
tinuing after  the  law  was  passed  with  a  summary  each  year  of  current 
information. 

These  reports  give  the  volume  of  business  by  the  groups,  a  list  of 
associations  at  that  time  filing  papers,  and  a  discussion  of  current 
trade  conditions,  advantages  obtained  and  obstacles  met  by  the  Webb 
law  associations.  Excerpts  from  the  annual  reports,  1937  to  1939J  are 
herewith  transmitted  as  exhibits."  When  a  new  association  is  formed^ 
the  Commission  issues  a  brief  statement  announcing  .the  filing  or 
papers.  Other  publicity  statements  have  been  issued  from  time  to 
time,  and  several  articles  have  been  prepared  for  publication  in  Com- 
merce Reports  published  by  the  Department  of  Commerce. 


"  See  exhibits  8.  9,  and  10  herewith,  excerpts  from  the  Commission's  reports  for  1937. 
1938,  and  1939. 


257769— 41~Xo.  6 10 


PKOCEDURE  UNDER  THE  ACT 

The  Commission's  procedure  under  the  act  has  been  simple.  Organi- 
zation papers  are  received  and  acted  upon  by  the  full  Commission. 
These  papers  include  the  first  report,  for  which  blanks  are  supplied 
by  the  Commission/  the  certificate  of  incorporation,  if  it  is  incor- 
porated, bylaws,  membership  agreement,  contract  forms,  working 
rules  or  regulations,  or  any  other  documents  covering  the  organization 
plan. 

Annual  reports  filed  in  January  of  each  year  ^  keep  the  organization 
material  to  date.  Other  information  is  required  from  time  to  time, 
and  field  calls  are  made  at  the  association  offices.  In  case  of  an  inquiry, 
a  more  extended  search  is  made  of  the  association  records  and  opera- 
tion. As  a  rule  inquiries  have  resulted  in  informal  advice  to  the 
association  in  question.  The  only  formal  summons  and  recommenda- 
tion was  issued  in  the  case  of  the  Pacific  Forest  Industries,  herehi- 
before  quoted. 

1  See  exhibit  4  herewltli,  first  report  form. 
'  See  exhibit  5  herewith,  annual  report  form. 

132 


PRODUCTS  EXPORTED— VALUE  OF  EXPORTS,  1920-38 

The  first  associations  to  be  formed  were  the  lumber  exporters,  the 
copper  and  steel  associations,  exporters  of  machinery,  pipe  fittings, 
and  valves,  railway  equipment,  phosphate  rock,  chemicals,  paper, 
furniture,  buttons,  elastic  webbing,  and  a  number  of  exporters  of  food- 
stuffs. Some  of  the  groups  were  organized  for  the  purpose  of  selling 
goods  to  the  Allies  during  the  World  War. 

The  sulfur  and  rubber  groups  were  formed  in  1922,  and  in  1923 
abrasives,  railway  tires  and  springs,  naval  stores,  and  corn  products 
were  added  to  the  list.  In  1924  associations  were  formed  to  ship  cot- 
ton linters  and  flour,  and  in  1925,  California  dried  fruit,  barrel  staves, 
and  railway  brake  beams.  In  1926  the  second  copper  association  was 
formed,  also  groups  to  ship  salmon  and  screws.  In  1927  the  second 
dried-fruit  association  was  added,  and  groups  to  sell  plywood,  doors, 
zinc,  and  flour.  In  1928  the  second  steel  association  was  organized  (the 
first  steel  group  withdrew  in  1923,  but  some  of  the  same  members 
joined  the  second),  also  associations  to  ship  fresh  fruit,  rice,  and  sar- 
dines. In  1929  the  petroleum  associations  were  added,  as  well  as  the 
,  metal  lath,  abrasives,  rice,  and  two  lumber  associations.  In  1930  the 
textile  groups  were  formed,  two  lumber  associations,  the  carbon-black 
association,  and  a  group  to  ship  grapefruit;  in  1931  another  lumber 
group,  an  electrical  association,  and  a  railway  signal  association.    In 

1932  the  shook  exporters  were  organized.     No  groups  were  formed  in 

1933  or  1934.  In  1935  associations  were  formed  to  ship  carbon  black, 
plywood,  fruit,  and  wood  naval  stores.  In  1936  box  shooks,  plate 
glass,  alkali  (California),  and  dried  prunes  were  added  to  the  list; 
in  1937  fresh  friiit,  rice  from  the  Southern  States,  and  the  iron  and  steel 
scrap  association  which  operated  only  a  few  months.  In  1939  the 
potash  association  was  formed,  and  in  1939  a  wood  naval  stores  associa- 
tion containing  some  of  the  same  members  as  the  first  wood  naval  stores 
group,  also  associations  to  export  pencils  and  California  rice.  The 
last  group  to  be  formed  was  the  electrical  export  corporation,  papers 
filed  in  January  1940. 

Generally  speaking,  semimanufactured  products  have  lent  them- 
selves more  readily  to  Export  Trade  Act  organization,  since  they  may 
be  standardized  and  sold  under  general  rules  as  to  quality  and  quan- 
tity. Some  specialized  products,  however,  liave  been  sold  to  advantage, 
with  due  regard  for  trade-marks  and  brands  developed  by  individual 
members.  Agricultural  products  may  be  exported  by  such  associations, 
although  in  some  cases  exporters  of  farm  prodii,cts  have  organized 
under  the  sister  cooperative  acts  instead. 

The  products  exported  are  in  some  cases  of  the  same  kind  and  grade 
us  are  sold  in  the  domestic  market,  with  perhaps  different  packaging 
and  marking.  Goods  exported  must  be  more  securely  packed  for 
stowage  and  transshipment.  In  some  products,  however,  different 
markets  require  different  specifications  and  classifications  (i.  e.,  lum- 

133 


134 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


ber),  and  at  times  the  buyer  cannot  afford  the  prices  prevailing  in  this 
country  and  prefers  to  buy  a  cheaper  grade  within  his  mfans. 

In  reporting  to  Congress  each  year  the  value  of  exports  oy  the  Webb 
law  associations,  they  have  been  divided  roughly  into  five  groups,  in 
order  that  the  statistics  of  the  individual  companies  need  not  be  pub- 
lished. Total  exports  during  the  years  1920  to  1938,  inclusive,  as  pub- 
lished in  the  reports  for  1921  to  1939,  are  as  follows : 


Year 

Metals  and 

metal 
products  1 

Products  of 

mines  and 

wells  « 

Lumber  and 

wood 

products ' 

Foodstuffs  * 

other  manu- 
factured 
products  * 

Total 

1920       

$152,000,000 
67,557,000 

$8, 000, 000 
5,  556, 000 

$17, 000, 000 
9,  894, 000 

$8,000,000 
5, 839, 000 

$36,000,000 
2, 334, 000 

$221,000,000 

1921       

91,180,000 

1922 «            -       .  - 

1923                  

68,  227, 000 
43,992,000 
43,  287, 000 
56,  500, 000 
180, 000, 000 
267,600,000 
271,000,000 
208, 000, 000 
100,000,000 
21,000,000 
29, 000, 000 
27,000.000 
20,250.000 
40,  507,  335 
93,  958, 850 
67,000,000 

10,500,000 
9,  885, 000 

14,  279. 000 
14.300.000 

15,  200, 000 
17,  500, 000 

270. 000, 000 
315,000,000 
73. 000, 000 
56, 000, 000 
44,000,000 
53, 000.  000 
55. 875, 000 
40,  780,  283 
32,  580,  219 
20, 920,  491 

26,000,000 

32,  700, 000 

38  000, 000 

35,700.000 

35,400.000 

28,  200, 000 

26,000.000 

22,  500, 000 

35,  400, 000 

8,000,000 

8,000.000 

8,  .500. 000 

9. 450, 000 

8,  533.  374 

7.  456,  922 

5,881.028 

32,  400, 000 
35,  300, 000 
42,000,000 
35, 000. 000 
53, 000, 000 
80,  400, 000 
67,100,000 
40,  500, 000 
32,  500, 000 
24,000,000 
28,000,000 
21,300,000 
16,500.000 
21,  250, 433 
19,  921,  343 
21, 487,  274 

16, 373, 000 
18,123,000 
27,934,000 
59,000,000 
87, 900, 000 
82,  500, 000 
90,000,000 
75, 000, 000 
70,  100, 000 
35, 000, 000 
34.000.000 
36, 000, 000 
35,610,000 
38,  225, 100 
43,  958,  498 
45,956,027 

153,500,000 

1924           

140,000,000 

1925       

165.  500, 000 

1926 - 

200,500,000 

1927 

371,500,000 

1928        

476,  200, 000 

1929    

724, 100. 000 

1930 

661,000,000 

1931 

311,000,000 

1932  .    

144, 000, 000 

1933 --- 

143, 000, 000 

1934           

145.800,000 

1935       

137,685,000 

1936 

149,  296,  525 

1937                    

197,  875, 832 

1938      

151,  244, 820 

<  r^opper,  iron  and  steel,  scrap,  metal  lath,  zinc,  machinery  and  implements,  foundry  equipment,  locomo- 
tives and  railway  equipment,  electrical  apparatus,  signal  apparatus,  tools,  pipes,  valves,  and  screws. 
>  Phosphate  rock,  cnal  and  coke,  sulfur,  petroleum  and  products,  carbon  black,  potash. 

*  Pine,  fir,  hardwood,  red  gum,  redwood,  walnut,  naval  stores,  plywood,  doors,  furniture  and  office  equip- 
ment, wood  pipe,  barrel  and  box  shocks,  wooden  tool  handles,  clothespins,  pencils  (pencil  association  newly 
organized,  exports  not  yet  included  in  totals). 

*  Canned  milk,  meat  products,  sugar,  flour,  corn,  and  other  grain  products,  rice,  sardines,  canned  salmon, 
peas  and  other  canned  vegetables,  fruit  (canned,  fresh  and  dried). 

'  Paper,  rubber  products,  abrasives,  cement,  glass,,  cotton  linters,  webbing  and  other  textiles,  clothing, 
buttons,  fertilizer,  paint  and  varnish,  insecticides,  alcohol,  tanning  materials,  soda  pulp,  soda  ash,  alkali,  and 
other  chemicals,  and  general  merchandise. 

'  Figures  not  compiled  in  1922. 

The  value  of  the  Webb  law,  however,  cannot  be  measured  in  dollars 
and  cents.  The  most  successful  years  were  not  those  in  which  the 
exports  reached  the  highest  figures.  The  real  measure  of  success  was 
achieved  in  the  period  of  depression  when  totals  were  smaller  but 
exporters,  beset  by  trade  restrictions  and  unsettled  markets  abroad, 
.were  still  able  to  continue  their  organization  and  ship  to  foreign  coun- 
tries through  their  cooperative  agreements. 


NUMBER  OF  ASSOCIATIONS  AND  OF  MEMBER 
COMPANIES 

The  association  lists  show  some  changes  each  year.  The  number  has 
varied  from  43  in  1920  to  57  in  the  peak  years,  1929  to  1931.  There  are 
now,  in  February  1940,  44  associations  on  file  with  the  Commission.^ 

The  Commission's  list,  published  in  the  annual  reports,  as  of  June 
30  of  each  year,  has  been  as  follows : 

1920,  43  associations.  1930,  57  associations. 

1921,  48  "  1931,  57 

1922,  56  "  1932,  51  " 

1923,  55  "  1933,  50 

1924,  50  "  1934,  45  " 

1925,  50  "  1935,  43  " 

1926,  51  "  1936,  45 

1927,  55  "  1937,  45 

1928,  56  "  1938,  44  " 

1929,  57  "  1939,  43  " 

Four  associations  have  been  in  operation  since  the  first  year  the  law 
was  passed,  1918.  These  and  7  others  have  been  in  active  operation 
for  20  years ;  and  25  associations  have  been  in  continuous  operation  for 
the  past  10  years, 

A  total  of  2,074  producers,  mills,  mines,  and  factories,  scattered 
throughout  the  United  States,  from  coast  to  coast,  and  shipping  to  all 
parts  of  the  world,  have  operated  under  the  act  during  its  operation, 
1918  to  Januarjr  1940.* 

The  present  list  of  44  associations  represents  434  member  companies. 


1  See  exhibit  2  herewith,  list  of  associations  filing  napers  with  the  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission on  Feb.  29,  1940.  These  include  three  new  groups  formed  since  the  last  annual 
report  of  the  Commission,  as  of  June  30,  1939  (Pencil  Industry  Export  Association, 
California  Rice  Exporters,  and  Electrical  Export  Corporation)  ;  and  exclude  two  that  have 
withdrawn  since  that  date   (Grapefruit  Distributors,  Inc.,  and  U.  S.  Handle  Export  Co.). 

'  See  exhibit  3  herewith,  list  of  associations  that  have  filed  papers,  1918-39,  with  names 
of  members  and  the  years  in  which  they  held  membership — also  notes  on  operation  of  each 
association,  and  if  dissolved,  rea'sons  for  dissolution. 

135 


TYPES  OF  ORGANIZATION 

In  view  of  the  wide  variety  of  products  that  have  been  exported 
under  the  act,  the  association  agreements  have  varied  considerably, 
each  drafted  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  particular  industry  to  be 
served.    The  three  general  types  that  have  been  used  are: 

(1)  The  association  that  serves  as  a  central  agent  for  the 
members,  taking  orders,  negotiating  sales,  and  handling  ship- 
ment of  the  goods  to  foreign  countries. 

(2)  The  association  that  directs  the  exportation  of  the  mem- 
bers and  retains  certain  functions  in  export  trade,  but  permits 
the  members  to  take  the  orders  through  their  already  established 
agents  abroad ;  and 

(3)  The  export  company  formed  for  the  purpose  of  buying 
the  members'  products  and  reselling  them  in  foreign  markets. 

The  first  and  second  methods  of  operation  may  be  combined,  the 
members  using  their  established  agents  for  some  markets  and  the 
association  sales  office,  for  new  markets  or  those  in  which  the  trade 
is  not  of  sufficient  volume  to  warrant  the  expense  of  individual 
agents. 

Most  of  the  associations  have  become  incorporated,  under  State 
laws,  for  their  own  convenience,  although  the  Export  Trade  Act  does 
not  require  it.  An  office  that  is  actually  negotiating  sales  and  in- 
curring financial  obligations  finds  incorporation  of  advantage.  Cap- 
ital stock  is  held  by  the  exporting  members  and  is  therefore  not  sold 
in  the  open  market. 

Usually  the  Webb  law  group  is  formed  by  producers  or  manu- 
facturers of  the  same  or  similar  products,  and  there  may  be  more 
than  one  group  in  the  same  industry.  Several  associations  have  been 
formed  to  sell  miscellaneous  pr6ducts,  but  this  has  not  been  success- 
ful ;  ordinarily  an  agent  is  not  equipped  to  sell  more  than  one  line  of 
goods.  A  Webb  law  group  is  a  voluntary  organization  and  may  or 
.may  not  include  a  large  percentage  of  the  industry.  One  of  the 
lumber  export  associations  ships  redwood,  another  walnut,  but  sev- 
eral have  shipped  pine.  On  the  Pacific  coast  one  group  sells  dried 
fruit  packed  in  California  and  another  the  same  products  packed  in 
Oregon.  A  third  group  sells  only  one  kind  of  dried  fruit  (prunes) 
and  comprises  some  of  the  same  members  as  are  in  the  California 
dried  fruit  association.  A  petroleum  company  at  one  time  filed 
papers  under  the  act  and  was  at  the  same  time  a  member  of  a  larger 
petroleum  association  also  filing  papers.  The  two  phosphate  asso- 
ciations at  one  time  combined  to  form  a  third  group.  In  some  cases 
two  associations  operating  independently  have  had  a  cooperative 
relationship. 

Some  of  the  association  agreements  are  limited  to  specified  prod- 
ucts or  certain  named  markets;  others  provide  for  shipment  to  any 
136 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  137 

or  all  foreign  countries.  Most  of  the  groups  are  formed  for  the 
purpose  of  developing  a  regular  export  business,  year  in  and  year 
out;  although  in  special  instances  an  association  may  be  organized 
to  meet  a  special  need  or  a  temporary  purpose.  In  a  few  cases,  the 
association  operates  only  when  there  is  a  surplus  to  be  disposed  of 
in  export  markets.  The  membership  agreements  may  be  of  perma- 
nent duration,  or  they  may  be  drafted  for  a  limited  period  with 
provision  for  extension,  in  which  case  they  are  usually  extended  for 
longer  periods. 

An  association  may  have  more  than  one  class  of  members,  de- 
pendent upon  the  services  that  it  contracts  to  perform  for  them. 
One  association  has  a  "full"  membership  and  a  "limited"  member- 
ship; another  has  a  "packers"  division  and  a  "merchants"  division; 
some  have  members  that  are  stockholders  and  others  that  do  not 
hold  stock.  In  addition  to  the  products  of  the  members,  an  asso- 
ciation may  obtain  and  sell  the  products  of  other  manufacturers  to 
complete  its  foreign  orders. 

The  main  office  of  the  association  may  be  at  seaport  in  order  to 
handle  the  shipping  details,  or  it  may  be  in  the  locality  of  the 
member  mills  in  order  to  serve  as  a  convenient  meeting  place  for 
agreement  upon  export  policies.  Branch  offices  and  agencies  are 
maintained  in  this  country  and  abroad. 

Provision  may  be  made  for  dividends  or  distribution  of  profits  on 
the  basis  of  stock  holdings  or  on  actual  tonnage  shipped.  In  most 
cases,  however,  the  associations  operate  on  an  expense  basis,  the 
profits  accruing  to  the  individual  members.  Expenses  may  be  pro- 
rated in  accordance  with  the  amount  of  stock  held,  or  they  may  be 
covered  by  commissions  on  sales,  with  provision  for  assessments  in 
case  of  deficit.  If  the  members'  exports  are  of  approximately  equal 
volume,  expenses  may  be  borne  equally.  Some  associations  deduct 
the  expense  from  current  receipts  for  sales  before  distribution  to 
the, members;  others  make  periodical  assessments  to  cover  expenses 
actually  incurred.  In  some  cases  a  minimum  price  agreed  upon  is 
paid  to  the  membej*  when  the  sale  is  made,  and  an  additional  sum, 
representing  the  difference  between  the  minimum  price  and  the  actual 
price  obtained  from  the  foreign  buyer,  is  later  divided  among  the 
membership.  The  association  funds  may  include  a  small  membership 
fee  payable  when  a  company  joins,  or  there  may  be  a  substantial 
initiation  fee  which  is  held  to  cover  losses  or  penalties  in  case  of 
breach  of  the  agreement. 


FUNCTIONS  OF  THE  GROUPS 

SEl^t^ING  AS  EXPORT  SALES  AGENT  FOR  THE  MEMBERS 

This  was  the  primary  function  contemplated  when  the  law  was 
passed.    The  Commission  reported  to  Congress  in  1916  that — 

The  principal  form  of  cooperation  in  the  mind  of  those  proposing  any  form  of 
cooperative  organization  was  the  joint  selling  agency.  (Federal  Trade  Commis- 
sion Report  on  Cooperation  in  American  Export  Trade,  1916,  vol.  1,  p.  244.) 

The  House  Committee  on  the  Judiciary  in  favorably  reporting  the 
bill  to  Congress  stated  that — 

The  object  of  this  bill  is  to  aid  and  encourage  our  manufacturers  and  producers 
to  extend  our  foreign  trade. 

The  bill  seeks  to  do  this  by  permitting  the  organization  of  cooperative  selling 
agencies  or  associations  among  American  exporters  in  order  that  they  may  meet 
foreign  competition  on  equal  terms  in  international  commerce.  (Rept.  No.  118, 
€4th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  August  15,  1916,  to  accompany  H.  R.  17350. ) 

During  the  first  few  years  of  Webb  law  operation  all  of  the  groups 
were  formed  on  this  basis.  A  her  the  Silver  letter  in  1924  other  types 
of  organizations  were  develoj  ^d.  The  effect  of  the  Commission's  rec- 
ommendations in  the  Pacific  Forest  Industries  case  in  January  1940 
(hereinbefore  set  forth)  will  be  to  limit  the  exclusive  selling  agency 
plan  of  operation  to  sales  in  foreign  markets  and  to  prohibit  combina- 
tion for  the  purpose  of  selling  to  domestic  competitors  of  the  associa- 
tions. 

The  association  that  actually  negotiates  export  sales  has  a  more 
extensive  office,  usually  at  seaport,  and  employs  agents  abroad  to  take 
orders  and  introduce  the  products  in  new  markets.  It  must  be  in  con- 
stant touch  with  the  members  by  telephone  and  through  committee 
meetings.  It  may  also  maintain  foreign  offices  and  traveling  agents  to 
cover  a  number  of  countries  and  direct  the  sales  of  regional  agents. 
This  is  the  most  economical  method  of  operation.  By  centralizing 
the  sales  offices  and  activities  of  the  members,  the  association  may  effect 
substantial  savings  in  cost.  For  the  smaller  company  or  the  producer 
who  has  not  developed  an  export  business,  this  method  is  invaluable ; 
in  many  cases  it  spells  the  difference  between  exporting  and  not  export- 
ing, because  the  member  company  cannot  afford  to  establish  foreign 
contacts  and  sell  individually. 

PURCHASING   THE  MEMBERS'   PRODUCTS   FOR  RESALE  IN    FOREIGN    MARKETS 

Some  associations  are  export  companies  that  buy  the  members'  prod- 
ucts and  resell  them  abroad  at  whatever  profit  can  be  made.  In  such 
a  case  the  members  may  sell  at  an  agreed  price,  f .  a.  s.  United  States 
ports,  and  the  association  then  negotiates  sales  to  foreign  purchasers 
at  a  delivered  price  fixed  by  the  management,  varying  with  foreign 
market  conditions,  ocean  freights,  insurance,  handling,  and  ware- 
house costs. 
138 


CONCENTRATION  OF  E<X)NOMIC  POWER  139 

The  corporation  may  guarantee  to  take  from  each  member  a  cer- 
tain amount  available  for  export  within  a  given  period.  One  such 
corporation  sells  to  distributors,  delivered  at  foreign  ports,  the  dis- 
tributors having  their  own  agents  in  the  various  foreign  markets. 
Stocks  abroad  are  held  by  the  distributors  or  their  agents.  The  ship- 
ments are  consolidated  and  the  association  effects  economy  in  arrang- 
ing for  freight,  cargo  space,  and  insurance. 

EMPLOYING  AGENTS  AND  DIRECTING  AGENTS  OF  THE  MEMBERS PROMOTING 

CONFERENCES  AND  AGREEMENTS  IN  EXPORT  TRADE 

If  the  members  have  well-established  export  departments  or  corpo- 
rations, they  may  not  wish  to  relinquish  them  and  sell  entirely  through 
a  central  sales  office  or  corporation.  In  that  case  the  members  agree 
upon  export  policies,  and  the  association  may  direct  the  activities  of 
the  members'  sales  offices.  The  extent  of  this  direction  depends  upon 
agreement ;  in  some  cases  the  members'  foreign  agents  are  under  con- 
tract with  the  association. 

This  sort  of  an  organization  is  also  available  for  the  development 
of  new  markets ;  and  in  the  depression  period,  when  it  was  necessary 
to  release  individual  agents  in  markets  where  the  trade  had  lessened, 
a  joint  agent  for  the  members  under  association  direction  was  utilized 
to  advantage. 

There  are  many  export  functions,  hereinafter  covered,  that  may  be 
;»dopted  by  an  association  of  this  sort,  but  the  principle  of  such  a 

Cup  is  a  cooperative  relationship  and  exchange  of  export  informa- 
i.  Prices  on  foreign  sales  may  or  may  not  be  fixed.  There  is 
usually  an  adoption  of  uniform  contract  forms.  There  may  be  a 
division  of  business  or  each  member  may  sell  what  it  can  abroad.  If 
the  association  is  at  seaport,  it  may  act  as  a  forwarder,  negotiating 
for  freight  and  insurance.  An  important  function  of  such  a  group 
is  an  exchange  of  information  as  to  special  sales  or  unusual  condi- 
tions. If,  for  instance,  the  goods  are  such  as  will  deteriorate  with  age, 
it  may  be  necessary  at  times  to  unload  certain  quantities  at  special 
prices.  Upon  notice  of  such  sales  the  other  members  of  the  group 
may  stay  out  of  the  market,  instead  of  trying  to  meet  the  cut  prices 
and  thereby  sustaining  loss.  Trade  practices  may  be  agreed  upon 
and  abuses  eliminated,  and  foreign-market  information  exchanged  for 
the  benefit  of  all  of  the  members. 

EXPLOITATION  OF  MEMBERS'  PRODUCTS  ABROAD 

The  export  association  is  in  a  position  to  effect  a  substantial  saving 
in  exploitation  expense.  For  instance,  a  group  formed  by  10,  20,  or 
50  mills  may  divide  the  expense  of  an  agent  among  them  and  can 
therefore  afford  to  send  representatives  all  over  the  world  to  introduce 
their  products  and  to  study  the  needs  of  each  market. 

A  system  of  joint  advertising  may  be  devised,  an  association  mark 
may  be  used  (such  as  "Wesco"  for  the  Walnut  Export  Sales  Co.,  or 
"Apec"  for  the  American  Provisions  Export  C5o.)  or  the  members' 
Jbrands  and  patented  articles  may  be  promoted  by  the  association 
agents. 


140  OONCBNTBATION  OF  BOONOMIC  POWER 

AGREEMENT  UPON  TERMS  AND  SALES  POLICIES  IN  EXPORT  TRADE 

Most  associations  have  adopted  a  uniform  sales  contract,  which 
eliminates  as  far  as  possible  trade  abuses  and  terms  that  have  been 
proven  impracticable.  In  some  cases  this  has  been  the  greatest  advan- 
tage derived  under  the  act. 

Price  agreements  vary  considerably.  Some  associations  do  not  fix 
export  prices,  but  the  members  agree  to  exchange  price  information ; 
this,  as  stated  before,  is  especially  useful  in  case  of  special  sales  for 
limited  periods.  The  common  practice  of  foreign  buyers  to  play  oi» 
exporter  out  against  another  in  an  attempt  to  beat  the  price  down,  may 
be  eliminated  if  each  knows  exactly  the  quotations  made  by  the  others 
for  export  sales. 

In  some  cases  a  minimum  export  price  is  agreed  upon,  below  which 
the  members  will  not  sell.  If  the  association  negotiates  the  sales,  more 
often  the  price  is  fixed  by  the  agent  abroad,  varying  in  different  mar- 
kets to  meet  the  local  conditions.  On  some  commodities  the  final  price 
is  a  matter  of  dicker  over  the  telephone  by  the  association  office  with 
the  foreign  purchasing  agents. 

Price,  credit,  and  operation  under  foreign-exchange  regulations  have 
presented  serious  problems  to  the  Webb  law  groups.  In  this  connec- 
tion we  may  quote  from  a  report  received  from  an  association  which 
has  been  in  active  operation  for  a  number  of  years  and  has  success- 
fully weathered  the  storm  of  the  depression. 

The  establishment  of  prices  is  a  distinct  function  of  the  association.  It  has  to 
be  under  our  form  of  operation.  Prices  are  established  and  maintained  by  re- 
sponsible foreign  agents  over  whom  supervision  is  exercised  by  an  association  offi- 
cial who  travels  abroad.  Prices  must  depend  upon  economic  conditions  in  each 
market  versus  maximum  consuming  power  of  that  market  under  normal  con- 
ditions. In  other  words,  purchasing  power  is  an  important  factor  to  be  considered 
with  respect  to  maximum  sales.  -Another  factor  is  competition ;  still  another  is 
quality  and  a  study  of  the  needs  of  important  consumers  in  accordance  with 
their  processes  of  manufacturing.  Prices  necessarily  fluctuate  in  different  parts 
of  the  world,  being  controlled  by  innumerable  conditions,  both  political  and  eco- 
nomic. In  some  instances  the  return  exceeds  domestic  levels  here ;  in  others  it 
is  about  the  same ;  and  in  others  it  will  occasionally  dip  lower.  Consequently  we 
work  on  a  final  average  annual  price  for  export,  which  in  turn  is  distributed  equi- 
tably in  proportion  to  each  factory's  shipments. 

Credits  range  according  to  market  practices  and  the  standing  of  customers. 
Exchange  is  a  chapter  in  itself.  There  is  the  problem  of  covering  future  exchange, 
spot  exchange,  and  operating  with  no  exchange  whatsoever.  We  have  a  free 
movement  of  exchange,  semi-embargoes,  and  complete  embargoes.  This  involves 
much  in  the  way  of  difficult  financing. 

In  one  country  we  have  operated  at  a  maximum  of  1  year  without  securing 
one  dollar  of  exchange,  allowing  our  funds;  to  accumulate  and  eventually  liqui- 
dating them  through  an  easement  in  exchange  regulations  over  a  period  of  a  year 
thereafter.  These  adversities  cause  much  in  the  loss  of  interest,  and  at  times 
much  more  in  depreciated  exchange,  when  available,  as  compared  to  the  rate  when 
sales  were  made.  Where  possible  we  cover  exchange  futures  as  far  in  advance 
as  6  months ;  in  other  cases  local  trends  indicate  spot  coverage  over  different 
periods ;  again  customers  have  been  permitted  to  hedge  exchange  and  provide 
necessary  guaranties  against  loss  in  our  acceptance  of  local  currency.  Sales 
are  made  in  sterling  to  markets  with  a  different  standard  of  currency. 

Constant  changes  in  foreign  tariffs  come  to  us  telegi-aphically  and  in  ample 
time  for  us  to  adopt  necessary  safeguards  by  advance  shipments  in  order  to  save 
large  sums  of  money. 

At  the  very  least,  a  maintained  price  level  t^an  return  from  20  to  30  percent  less 
than  circumstances  seem  to  warrant,  and  even  reach  a  point  where  exports  are 
blocked  completely  over  certain  periods.    This  involves  heavy  stocking  of  ware- 


CONCENTRATION  UF  ECONOMIC  POWER  141 

houses  abroad  in  advance,  increased  expenses  and  uncertainty  regarding  even 
an  approximated  price  return. 

This  fact  alone  illustrates  the  tremendous  advantage  of  associated  activity  in 
contrast  to  individual  effort. 

Some  associations  report  that  export  prices  are  fixed  by  the  council 
or  board  of  directors,  or  by  a  special  committee  for  that  purpose,  "all 
factors  considered." 

In  some  cases  sales  are  made  cash  against  documents,  and  in  some 
countries  quotations  are  in  American  dollars,  the  buyer  paying  the 
tariffs.  The  usual  practices  obtain  in  quoting  c.  i.  f.,  f .  a.  s.,  or  f.  o.  b. 
vessel  at  loading  point  for  the  convenience  of  the  foreign  purchaser. 

ALLOCATION    OF   THE   EXPORT   BUSINESS 

The  association's  business  may  be  divided  among  the  member  com- 
panies in  predetermined  proportions  or  quotas.  Various  bases  are 
adopted;  in  some  cases  the  stock  holding  of  a  member  decides  his 
proportion;  in  others  the  tonnage  is  divided  on  the  basis  of  past 
exports  over  a  period  a^eed  upon,  or  upon  reports  covering  amounts 
available  for  export  within  a  future  period.  Some  quota  plans  are 
more  complicated,  including  consideration  of  quality  as  well  as  quan- 
tity, loading  and  shipping  facilities,  and  other  export  factors.  Provi- 
sion is  usually  made  for  readjustment  of  quotas  to  meet  changing 
conditions. 

In  order  to  maintain  a  quota  system,  the  association  must  have  de- 
tailed records  of  the  members'  sales,  with  copies  of  invoices  and  other 
documents. 

Some  associations  have  no  quota  plan,  each  member  taking  whatever 
orders  it  can  obtain.  In  that  case  the  association  need  not  keep  such 
detailed  records. 

STANDARDIZATION    OF   PRODUCTS    EXPORTED INSPECTION    AND    CLAIMS 

SERVICE 

Much  has  been  accomplished  by  the  Webb  law  groups  toward  stand- 
ardization of  the  goods  exported,  and  improvement  of  their  quality. 
If  an  association  mark  is  adopted,  all  goods  bearing  that  mark  must 
meet  a  certain  quality  test.  For  this  purpose  the  smaller  members 
may  have  the  benefit  of  the  technical  research  of  the  larger  companies. 

Reduction  in  the  number  of  sizes  and  shapes  of  the  products  sold 
in  export  has  tended  to  lessen  manufacturing  cost,  and  the  associa- 
tions' efforts  to  learn  the  needs  of  foreign  buyers  as  to  specification 
or  grade  have  made  for  increased  export  sales.  If  cheaper  goods  are 
sold,  to  meet  the  lower  purchasing  power  of  foreign  buyers,  these 
grades  are  established  without  deception  in  order  to  protect  the  repu- 
tation of  tlie  association  products. 

Inspection  service  before  shipment  has  reduced  the  claims  of  for- 
eign buyers.  Provision  has  also  been  made  for  the  handling  and 
settlement  of  disputes  through  association  agents. 

Eules  are  adopted  for  packing  and  shipment.  These  must  conform 
to  the  requirements  of  the  markets  in  which  the  goods  are  sold.  The 
association  is  in  a  position  to  obtain  information  as  to  these  require- 
ments and  to  advise  the  members  with  a  minimum  of  expense. 


142  OONCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

ARRANGING  FOR  INSURANCE,  FREIGHT  RATES,  CARGO  SPACE,  SHIPPING  DATES, 

AND  OTORAOE 

The  association  that  negotiates  sales  usually  has  forwarding  func- 
tions, and  in  some  cases  where  the  sales  are  conducted  by  the  members, 
the  association  offices  are  used  for  the  purpose  of  obtaining  advan- 
tageous freight  rates,  cargo  space  and  shipping  dates.  Consolidation 
of  shipments  and  arrangement  for  space  over  a  longer  period  make 
for  better  rates  on  freight  and  insurance.  Some  of  the  associations 
have  handled  negotiations  with  conferences  which  no  one  member  was 
in  a  position  to  do. 

Storage  in  this  country  or  abroad  is  at  times  to  the  advantage  of  the 
producers.  This  is  especially  true  of  a  seasonal  product  which  would 
otherwise  come  upon  the  market  at  one  time  of  the  year.  If  the 
goods  can  be  disposed  of  with  regularity,  depression  of  price  may  be 
avoided. 

It  has  also  been  found  that  transportation  lines  are  more  crowded 
at  some  seasons.  The  association  may  therefore  arrange  to  have  its 
goods  transported  at  dull  seasons  and  stored  at  port  for  future  ship- 
ment ;  this  is  especially  true  of  heavy  cargo. 

COLLECTING  AND  DISSEMINATINQ,  TRADE  INFORMATION  AS  TO  MARKET  CON- 
DITIONS ABROAD,  CREDITS,  EXCHANGE,  SHIPPING  REGULATIONS,  AND 
FOREIGN  LAWS 

The  association  is  in  a  position  to  obtain  information  concerning 
trade  conditions  in  foreign  markets  that  is  not  available  to  individual 
members  without  considerable  expense.  Changes  in  regulations  are 
reported  by  the  association  agents  by  cable  or  telegraph,  and  relayed 
to  the  members  in  time  for  the  adoption  of  necessary  safeguards  and 
the  saving  of  large  sums  of  money.  This  has  been  of  especial  value 
during  the  past  rew  years  when  war  conditions  have  upset  the  mem- 
bers' markets.    One  association  reported  in  1938  that : 

With  war  clouds  on  the  horizon,  we  were  enabled  to  keep  careful  track  of 
shipments  en  route,  divert  them  to  diflEerent  ports,  or  hold  them  in  warehouses 
at  European  ports  until  the  situation  cleared  and  we  could  complete  delivery. 
Thus  no  credit  losses  were  sustained  from  territories  which  M'ere  taken  over 
by  Germany. 

Foreign-exchange  regulations  abroad  have  been  numerous,  and 
other  import  restrictions  such  as  tariffs,  import  quotas,  and  blocked 
accounts,  have  complicated  the  export  procedure,  and  made  cooperative 
effort  of  value  to  individual  exporters. 


ADVANTAGES  DEKIVED  BY  COOPERATIVE  EFFORT 

Advantages  obtained  from  the  various  functions  discussed  above 
are  obvious.  The  more  functions  the  association  adopts  the  greater 
economy  may  be  effected  by  cooperative  action. 

A  centralized  agency  may  save  large  sums  in  sales  cost.  The  asso- 
ciation can  obtain  better  freight  rates  and  insurance  policies  by  con- 
solidating shipments,  or  by  negotiating  with  conferences  and  steam- 
ship lines.  It  is  also  in  a  position  to  represent  the  members  before 
governmental  boards  and  trade  officials — that  is,  in  connection  with 
reciprocal  tariff  hearings  in  this  country,  or  exchange-commission 
officials  abroad. 

Pooling  the  members'  products  or  storing  them  in  warehouses  makes 
it  possible  to  feed  them  into  foreign  markets  throughout  the  year  at 
advantageous  prices.  In  some  cases  the  association  may  fill  an  order 
by  drawing  uj)oh  the  supplies  of  a  number  of  members,  whereas  one 
could  not  furnish  the  entire  cargo.  There  is  also  an  advantage  to  the 
foreign  buyer  if  he  can  make  his  selection  from  a  varied  assortment 
of  products  not  available  in  one  mill,  but  representing  the  production 
of  all  of  the  members  of  such  a  group. 

Agreements  upon  price  and  terms  of  sale,  and  adoption  of  uniform 
contracts,  are  of  advantage  to  the  American  seller  and  also  to  the 
foreign  buyer  who  prefers  a  price  and  terms  that  do  not  fluctuate 
daily.  Trade  abuses  have  been  eliminated  and  service  improved  by 
agreement  on  terms.  The  association  that  acts  as  a  clearing  house  for 
the  members'  export  sales  serves  a  useful  purpose  with  a  minimum 
expense. 

Standardization  and  improvement  of  quality  have  raised  the  stand- 
ard of  American  exports;  the  association  inspection  service  reduces 
claims  of  buyers  and  offers  an  efficient  method  of  handling  disputes. 

The  association  may  riot  only  effect  an  orderly  merchandising  of 
the  goods,  butr  it  may  provide  by  united  action  financial  support  for 
trade  development.  The  expense  of  such  service  divided  among  a 
number  of  members  can  well  be  afforded  by  each. 

To  meet  centralized  buying  by  centralized  selling,  and  to  stand  up 
against  the  competition  of  well-established  foreign  combines  or  cartels, 
are  very  important  advantages.     One  association  has  reported  that: 

Only  by  combination  under  the  Webb  law  and  actingas  a  unit,  can  the  American 
producers  in  this  industry  successfully  meet  the  competition  of  foreign  producers. 
There  is  little  doubt,  we  think,  that  if  the  American  producers  had  not  been  able 
or  had  neglected  to  take  full  advantage  of  the  provisions  of  the  Webb-Pomerene 
law,  to  combine  and  make  joint  effort,  this  American  product  would  have  been 
driven  out  of  foreign  markets  many  years  ago. 

In  combining  under  the  Webb  law,  however,  these  producers  have 
not  had  undue  advantage  in  foreign  markets.  They  have  merely  been 
placed  on  an  equal  footing  with  foreigners  in  countries  where  coml>ina- 
tion  in  trade  is  permitteu  and  encouraged. 

143 


■[44  OUiSCENTRATlON  OF  KCO^\JMIC  POWER 

Some  associations  have  reported  that  they  were  "formed  to  meet 
chaos  in  prices,  terms,  and  conditions  of  sale  in  all  foreign  markets" 
at  the  time  of  their  organization.  Asked  to  what  they  attribute  their 
success,  one  group  said : 

Success  of  this  conjpany,  as  a  Webb-Pomerene  organization,  is  due  chiefly  to 
the  fact  that  we  have  gone  into  the  business  of  foreign  trade  in  what  we  feel 
is  an  intelligent  manner  and  have  followed  a  consistent  policy  year  in  and 
year  out,  in  good  times  and  in  poor  times,  of  maintaining  a  foreign  field  organ- 
ization. Through  such  organization  we  have  been  enabled  to  build  up  and 
maintain  a  recognition  of  the  quality  of  our  brand.  This  quality  reputation, 
tpgether  with  the  goodwill  created  by  the  maintenance  of  a  continued  foreign 
sales  force,  has  enabled  us  to  continue  to  secure  business  even  in  the  face 
of  foreign  price  competition  of  a  very  serious  type. 

The  associations'  reports  to  the  Commission  state  these  advantages 
as  applied  to  each  year's  operation.    A  typical  report  may  be  quoted* 

In  connection  with  advantages  normally  accruing  to  operation  as  an  asso- 
ciation, we  experienced  all  the  usual  ones  due  to  cooperative  effort  and  might 
mention  three  general  and  two  specific  instances. 

Specifically. —  (1)  Due  to  fairly  large  individual  shipments  enabling  purchase 
of  considerable  cargo  space  at  a  time,  little  inconvenience  was  suffered  during 
the  maritime  strike  because  of  the  tie-up  of  some  lines.  Unaffected  lines  were 
glad  of  the  opportunity  to  obtain  a  portion  of  our  business. 

(2)  Advantage  of  sales  and  price  control  were  particularly  valuable  this  year 
in  view  of  impending  and  actual  devaluation  of  certain  European  currencies. 
The  association  was  enabled  to  act  for  the  industry  as  a  unit  in  determining 
proper  action  in  these  matters.  ,!^ 

Oenerally. — (1)  The  establishment -etf  recognition  of  our  house  mark,  especially 
created  for  the  export  field  on  the  formation  of  the  association,  so  that  within 
5  years  it  has  beconae  known  as  the  standard  quality  brand  wherever  our  products 
are  sold. 

(2)  Adoption  of  a  standard  export  packing  method  used  by  all  members  and 
governed  by  the  association,  the  effect  of  which  has  been  to  practically  eliminate 
all  complaints  of  damage  in  transit.  Corollary  to  this,  any  improvement  in  and 
savings  in  packing  costs  originated  by  any  one  member,  when  approved  by  the 
association  is  incorporated  into  the  method  and  made  available  to  all  members. 

(3)  Reduction  of  product  complaints  has  been  consistent  as  files  have  been 
built  into  case  histories  so  that  the  association  has  a  broad  picture  enabling 
it  to  determine  quickly  whether  complaints  are  justified,  and  if  so,  to  make 
quick  corrections  and  adjustments.  The  moral  effect  has  been  toward  fewer  and 
fewer  unfair  claims  from  the  trade,  as  the  latter  have  come  to  realize  the 
advantage  the  association  has  in  determining  such. 

Obstacles  encountered  are  similar  to  those  obtaining  luring  the  past  couple 
of  years,  the  main  ones  being  limited  to  quotas  for  import  of  American  mer- 
chandise under  a  permit  system,  one  of  the  varieties  of  which  requires  the 
deposit  of  the  importer's  currency  at  the  time  of  application  for  his  permit. 
He  is  then  required  to  get  the  merchandise  in  within  a  limited  period  of  time, 
i.  e.,  before  expiration  of  his  permit.  The  exporter  then  receives  dollar  exchange 
when  released  by  the  Exchange  Control  Board  and  this  may  be  fairly  prompt 
or  several  months,  depending  upon  the  amount  of  exchange  available  at  the 
time.  I  might  also  mention  that  the  revaluation  of  certain -gold-block  currencies 
at  lower  levels  gave  foreign  competitors  an  immediate  advantage,  but  this 
situation  tended  to  right  itself  with  rises  in  prices  in  the  foreign  markets  where 
the  local  manufacturers  are  dependent  upon  imported  raw  material  supplies. 

Other  reasons  for  the  success  of  the  Webb  law  groups  are  covered 
in  exhibit  3  herewith,  which  gives  information  concerning  each  asso- 
ciation individually. 


OBSTACLES  MET  BY  EXPORT  ASSOCIATIONS— REASONS 
FOR  DISSOLUTION  OF  SOME  OF  THE  GROUPS 

The  Commission  is  sometimes  asked  why  some  of  the  Webb-law 
groups  have  become  dissolved. 

The  chief  reasons,  of  course,  have  been  connected  with  depression 
conditions  during  the  past  10  years:  Difficulty  in  meeting  exchange 
requirements,  in  financing  shipments,  and  in  operating  under  uncer- 
tain credit  conditions.  Prices  abroad  have  been  consistently  lower 
than  in  this  country,  on  most  products ;  some  companies  were  unwilling 
or  unable  to  sell  at  such  low  prices,  and  went  out  of  the  export  business 
for  that  reason.  Some  groups  had  customers  abroad  who  were  willing 
to  paj^  the  price  but  the  goods  could  not  pass  under  import  quota  regu- 
lations, or  it  was  impossible  to  get  American  dollars  abroad,  to  pay 
for  the  exports.  Blocked  accounts  have  caused  serious  inconvenience 
and  loss. 

In  some  cases  associations  organized  to  meet  special  conditions  went 
out  of  business  when  their  objectives  were  accomplished.  This  was 
true  of  groups  formed  to  sell  to  the  Allies  during  the  World  War;  and 
some  that  served  the  purpose  of  disposing  of  war  stocks  after  the  war 
closed.  It  has  also  been  true  of  a  few  associations,  such  as  the  Nogales 
Garbanzo  Association  which  disposed  of  a  certain  accumulation  of 
chick  peas  and  then  discontinued  its  operation.  Some  of  the  lumber 
groups  went  out  of  business  because  the  source  of  supply  was  ex- 
hausted. 

Some  associations  dissolved  in  order  to  effect  new  organization  with 
anotlier  alinement  or  a  different  method  of  operation.  In  a  number 
of  instances  after  an  association  became  dissolved  some  of  its  members 
were  loath  to  lose  the  benefits  of  cooperation  and  therefore  joined  or 
formed  another  group. 

In  some  cases  the  association  was  not  successful  in  developing  a 
foreign  market,  due  to  lack  of  demand  or  the  competition  of  cheaper 
foreign  goods.  This  was  true  of  the  button  associations  which  found 
they  could  Jiot  compete  with  the  Japanese  product. 

If  sales  were  made  to  foreign  governments,  after  the  World  War, 
tliere  was  at  times  difficulty  in  obtaining  cash  in  payment.  Some 
associations  were  unwilHng  to  accept  bonds  or  other  Government  secur- 
ities in  lieu  of  cash,  and  therefore  did  not  make  sales.  Others  accepted 
securities  and  suffered  loss  upon  default  in  payment. 

In  the  case  of  some  foodstuffs,  the  post-war  policy  of  foreign  govern- 
ments to  develop  production  to  the  point  of  self-sufficiency  resulted  in 
tariffs  and  other  import  restrictions,  with  a  consequent  lessening  of 
purchases  from  this  country.  In  some  instances  this  led  to  the  build- 
ing of  American  plants  abroad,  which  compensated  for  loss  on  exports. 

Reasons  for  dissolution  are  mentioned  in  exhibit  No.  3  in  connection 
with  the  operation  of  the  individual  associations  therein  listed. 

145 


FUTURE  OF  THE  WEBB-POMERENE  LAW 

The  operation  of  the  Webb-law  groups  has  been  vitally  affected  by 
war  conditions.  The  act  came  into  effect  during  the  closing  chapter 
of  the  World  War.  It  was  used  to  some  advantage  in  furnishing 
products  for  the  use  of  the  Allies,  and  also  for  the  disposition  of  sur- 
plus war  stocks  after  the  armistice. 

During  the  reconstruction  period,  there  was  great  demand  for 
American  products  abroad,  and  large  orders  were  placed  to  complete 
rebuilding  plans.  The  slight  recession  felt  in  1921  and  1922  was 
followed  by  the  boom  period,  leading  up  to  the  peak  years  of  1928  and 
1929.  In  the  latter  year  the  Webb-law  groups  shipped  to  foreign 
countries  goods  valued  at  $724,100,000. 

The  necessity  for  self-sufficiency  in  case  of  future  wars  led  to  im- 
portant changes  in  European  production  and  trade.  Certain  indus- 
tries have  been  built  up  during  the  past  20  years  through  subsidies  and 
regulation,  tariffs  have  been  imposed,  and  imports  of  these  products 
from  the  United  States  were  lessened.  The  Webb-law  groups  felt 
these  changes  and  readjusted  their  markets  to  meet  them. 

The  depression  period,  as  an  aftermath  of  war,  appeared  first  in 
foreign  countries  and  was  met  by  the  governments  with  regulations 
looking  toward  a  lowering  of  prices  and  a  decrease  in  imports,  in 
order  to  prevent  violent  fluctuations  in  exchange.  Exchange  control, 
import  quota  plans,  barter  systems,  and  other  measures  abroad  had 
serious  effects  upon  American  exports.  In  some  cases  Webb-law  mem- 
bers were  unwilling  to  sell  at  the  lower  prices  prevailing  abroad,  and 
in  others  they  found  it  impossible  to  await  paj'ment  under  the  restric- 
tive measures.  It  was  difficult  to  meet  the  competition  of  lower- 
Ericed  goods  manufactured  in  foreign  countries,  at  times  subsidized 
y  foreign  governments  for  the  purpose  of  encouraging  trade. 

Under  these  conditions  it  is  surprising  that  so  many  Webb-law 
groups  continued  in  operation,  and  that  each  year  found  new  associa- 
tions forming  for  the  development  of  exportation.  It  appeared,  how- 
ever, that  the  difficulties  encountered  emphasized  the  necessity  for  co- 
operation and  brought  the  exporters  more  closely  together  in  their 
effort  to  continue  on  at  least  a  small  scale,  an  export  movement  that 
was  necessary  to  balance  the  productive  system  and  keep  the  local 
mills  and  mines  in  operation.  It  is  significant  that  although  the  value 
of  exports  dropped  to  $137,685,000  in  1935,  the  number  of  associations 
has  at  no  time  been  less  than  43.  Some  of  the  groups  continued  their 
organization  year  after  year,  with,  small  shipments,  in  the  hope  that 
the  depression  would  lift  and  foreign  trade  would  again  be  profitable. 
It  was  in  these  years  that  the  real  measure  of  success  was  achieved  for 
Webb-law  operation ;  in  many  instances  associations  reported  that 
they  would  have  been  unable  to  export  without  cooperative  effort. 

Internal  disturbances  in  the  South  and  Central  American  coun- 
tries, and  the  Sino-Jaj)anese  conflict  in  tlie  Orient,  necessitated  fur- 
146 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EICONOMIC  POWER  147 

ther  shifts  in  American  exports.  This  was  especially  true  of  export 
associations  on  the  west  coast  that  had  built  up  a  profitable  business 
in  China  and  now  find  that  market  closed.  On  the  other  hand,  war 
clouds  gathering  in  Europe  increased  the  demand  for  some  classes  of 
American  goods,  and  again  there  were  shifts  in  exports  across  the  At- 
lantic. 

The  present  conflict  in  Europe,  begun  in  September  1939,  has  pre- 
sented further  problems.  It  is  too  early  to  predict  just  what  the 
effecr  will  be,  and  reports  on  the  sales  of  the  associations  for  1939  are 
not  yet  in.^  Doubtless  there  are  some  products  which  are  now  in  de- 
mand by  belligerent  countries  vvliich  may  be  shipped  under  the  terms 
of  the  Neutrality  Act,  but  many  adjustments  will  be  necessary.  Some 
products  that  have  been  exported  to  the  countries  at  war  are  not  in- 
cluded in  the  lists  of  essentials  that  may  now  be  purchased.  Trans- 
portation facilities  are  in  a  state  of  reorganization ;  new  financing  and 
credit  plans  must  be  devised.  In  the  meantime  there  is  an  oppor- 
tunity for  development  of  trade  with  our  "good  neighbors"  on  the 
south  to  replace  products  that  they  have  heretofore  purchased  from 
Europe  and  cannot  now  obtain  from  that  source. 

There  is,  therefore,  a  renewed  interest  in  the  Export  Trade.  Act 
today.  The  association  type  of  organization  is  uppermost  in  the 
minds  of  exporters  because  no  one  company,  however  well  equipped, 
can  solve  the  problems  that  now  confront  our  industries  and  exporters. 
The  establishment  of  joint  purchasing  offices  representing  foreign 
countries  suggests  some  form  of  joint  selling  to  supply  their  needs. 
A  number  of  new  export  associations  are,  therefore,  under  considera- 
tion. 

In  reviewing  the  past  22  years  of  operation,  we  may  perhaps  fore- 
see the  future,  since  export  trade  today  is  in  much  the  same  position 
as  when  this  law  was  passed  in  1918 :  Before  it  lies  a  period  of  Euro- 
pean conflict  and  a  further  period  of  reconstruction.  Again  the  prob- 
lems of  shifting  markets,  uncertain  credit,  and  foreign-trade  restric- 
tions must  be  met  in  the  years  to  come.  Transportation  facilities  will 
again  be  changed  when  the  Neutrality  Act  and  other  war  conditions 
are  at  an  end.  Not  only  in  Europe,  but  in  the  Orient  there  will  be 
important  changes  and  tremendous  opportunities  for  the  development 
of  trade.  It  is  to  be  hoped  that  the  experience  of  the  past  will  be  of 
advantage  to  the  export  associations  in  meeting  the  problems  of  today 
and  tomorrow  through  cooperative  effort. 


*  This  report  prepared  In  February  1940. 


257769 — 41— No. 


APPENDIX 

EXHIBIT  1 

EXPORT   TRADE   ACT    (WEBB-POMERENE   LAW, 
40  STAT.  516) 

[Public — No.  126 — 65th  Congress] 

[H.  R.  2316] 
AN  ACT  To  promote  exjJort  trade,  and  for  other  purposes 

Be  it  ena  '  i  by  the  Senate  ana  House  of  Representatives  of  the 
United  States  of  America  in  Congress  assembled^  That  the  words 
"export  trade"  wherever  used  in  this  Act  mean  solely  trade  or  com- 
merce in  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise  exported,  or  in  the  course 
of  being  exported  from  the  United  States  or  any  Territory  thereof 
to  any  foreign  nation;  but  the  words  "export  trade"  shall  not  be 
deemed  to  include  the  production,  manufacture,  or  selling  for  con- 
sumption or  for  resale,  within  the  United  States  or  any.  Territory 
thereof,  of  such  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise,  or  any  act  in  the 
course  of  such  production,  manufacture,  or  selling  for  consumption 
or  for  resale. 

That  the  words  "trade  within  the  United  States"  wherever  used 
in  this  Act  mean  trade  or  commerce  among  the  several  States  or  in 
any  Territory  of  the  United  States,  or  in  the  District  of  Columbia, 
or  between  anj'  such  Territory  and  another,  or  between  any  such 
Territory  or  Territories  and  any  State  or  States  or  the  District  of 
Columbia,  or  between  the  District  of  Columbia  and  any  State  or 
States. 

That  the  word  "association"  wherever  used  in  this  Act  means  any 
corporation  or  combination,  by  contract  or  otherwise,  of  two  or  more 
persons,  partnerships,  or  corporations. 

Sec.  2.  That  nothing  contained  in  the  Act  entitled  "An  Act  to 
protect  trade  and  commerce  against  unlawful  restraints  and  monopo- 
lies," approved  July  second,  eighteen  hundred  and  ninety,  shall  be 
construed  as  declaring  to  be  illegal  an  association  entered  into  for 
the  sole  purpose  of  engaging  in  export  trade  and  actually  engaged 
solely  in  such  export  trade,  or  an  agreement  made  or  act  done  in  the 
course  of  export  trade  by  such  association,  provided  such  association, 
agreement,  or  act  is  not  in  restraint  of  trade  within  the  United  States, 
and  is  not  in  restraint  of  the  export  trade  of  any  domestic  com-. 
])etitor  of  such  association:  And  provided  further^  That  such  asso- 
ciation does  not,  either  in  the  United  States  or  elsewhere,  enter  into 
any  agreement,  understanding,  or  conspiracy,  or  do  any  act  which 
artificially  or  intentionally  enhances  or  depresses  prices  within  the 

149 


150  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

United  States  of  commodities  of  the  class  expyorted  by  such  associa- 
tion, or  which  substantially  lessens  competition  within  the  United 
States  or  otherwise  restrains  trade  therein. 

Sec.  3.  That  nothing  contained  in  section  seven  of  the  Act  entitled 
"An  Act  to  supplement  existinfr  laws  against  unlawful  restraints  and 
monopolies,  and  for  other  purposes,"  approved  October  fifteenth, 
nineteen  hundred  and  fourteen,  shall  be  construed  to  forbid  the 
acquisition  or  ownership  by  any  corporation  of  the  whole  or  any  part 
of  the  stock'  or  other  capital  of  any  corporation  organized  solely  for 
the  purpose  of  engaging  in  export  trade,  and  actually  engaged  solely 
in  such  export  trade,  unless  the  effect  of  such  acquisition  or  owner- 
ship rnay  be  to  restrain  trade  or  substantially  lessen  competition 
within  the  United  States. 

Seo.  4.  That  the  prohibition  against  "unfair  methods  of  compe- 
tition" and  the  remedies  provided  for  enforcing  said  prohibition 
contained  in  the  Act  entitled  "An  Act  to  create  a  Federal  Trade 
Commission,  to  define  its  powers  and  duties,  and  for  other  purposes," 
approved  September  twenty-sixth,  nineteen  hundred  and  fourteen, 
shall  be  construed  as  extending  to  unfair  methods  of  competiftion 
used  in  export  trade  against  competitors  engaged  in  export  trade, 
even  though  the  acts  constituting  such  unfair  methods  are  done 
without  the  territorial  jurisdiction  of  the  United  States. 

Sec.  5.  That  every  association  now  engaged  solely  in  export  trade, 
within  sixty  days  after  the  passage  of  this  Act,  and  every  associa- 
tion entered  into  hereafter  which  engages  solely  in  export  trade, 
within  thirty  days  after  its  creation,  shall  file  with  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission  a  verified  written  statement  setting  forth  th^  location 
of  its  offices  or  places  of  business  and  the  names  and  addresses  of 
all  its  officers  and  of  all  its  stockholders  or  members,  and  if  a  cor- 
poration, a  copy  of  its  certificate  or  articles  of  incorporation  and 
bylaAvs,  and  if  unincorporated,  a  copy  of  its  articles  or  contract  of 
association,  and  on  the  first  day  of  January  of  each  year  thereafter 
it  shall  make  a  like  statement  of  the  location  of  its  officers  or  places 
of  business  and  the  names  and  addresses  of  all  its  officers  and  of  all 
its  stockholders  or  members  and  of  all  amendments  to  and  changes 
in  its  articles  or  certificate  of  incorporation  or  in  its  articles  or  con- 
tract of  association.  It  shall  also  furnish  to  the  commission  suah 
information  as  the  commission  may  require  as  to  its  organization, 
business,  conduct,  practices,  management,  and  relation  to  other  asso- 
ciations, corporations,  partnerships,  and  individuals.  Any  associa- 
tion which  shall  fail  so  to  do  shall  not  have  the  benefit  of  the  provi- 
sions of  section  two  and  section  three  of  this  Act,  and  it  shall  also 
forfeit  to  the  United  States  the  sum  of  $100  for  each  and  every  day 
of  the  continuance  of  such  failure,  which  forfeiture  shall  be  payable 
into  the  Treasury  of  the  United  States,  and  shall  be  recoverable  in  a 
civil  suit  in  the  name  of  the  United  States  brought  in  the  district 
where  the  association  has  its  principal  office,  or  in  any  district  in 
which  it  shall  do  business.  It  shall  be  the  duty  of  the  various  dis- 
trict attorneys,  under  the  direction  of  the  Attorney  General  of  the 
United  States  to  prosecute  for  the  recovery  of  the  forfeiture.  The 
costs  and  expenses  of  such  prosecution  shall  be  paid  out  of  the  ap- 
propriation for  the  expenses  of  the  courts  of  the  United  States. 

Wlienever  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  shall  have  reason  to 
believe  that  an  association  or  any  agreement  made  or  act  done  by 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EJOONOMIC  POWER  151 

such  association  is  in  restraint  of  trade  within  the  United  States  or 
in  restraint  of  the  export  trade  of  any  domestic  competitor  of  such 
association,  or  that  an  association  either  in  the  United  States  or 
elsewhere  has  entered  into  any  agreement,  understanding,  or  con- 
spiracy, or  done  any  act  which  artificially  or  intentionally  enhances 
or  depresses  prices  within  the  United  States  of  commodities  of  the 
class  exported  by  such  association,  or  which  substantially  lessens 
competition  within  the  United  States  or  otherwise  restrains  trade 
therein,  it  shall  summon  such  association,  its  officers,  and  agents  to 
appear  before  it,  and  thereafter  conduct  an  investigation  into  the 
alleged  violations  of  law.  Upon  investigation,  if  it  shall  conclude 
that  the  law  has  been  violated,  it  may  make  to  such  association 
recommendations  for  the  readjustment  of  its  business,  in  order  that 
it  may  thereafter  maintain  its  organization  and  management  and 
conduct  its  business  in  accordance  with  law.  If  such  association 
fails  to  comply  with  the  recommendations  of  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission,  said  commission  shall  refer  its  findings  and  recommen- 
dations to  the  Attorney  General  of  the  United  States  for  such  action 
thereon  as  he  may  deem  proper. 

For  the  purpose  of  enforcing  these  provisions  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission  shall  have  all  the  powers,  so  far  as  applicable,  given  it 
in  "An  Act  to  create  a  Federal  Trade  Commission,  to  define  its 
powers  and  duties,  and  for  other  purposes." 

Approved,  April  10,  1918. 


EXHIBIT  2 


44  ASSOCIATIONS  REPRESENTING  434  MEMBER  COM- 
PANIES FILING  PAPERS  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  FEBRUARY  1940 


American   Box  Shook  Export  Association,   Barr  Bldg., 

Washington,  D.  C. 
American  Hardwood  Exporters,  Inc.,  Carondelet  Bldg., 

New  Orleans,  La. 

American  Paper  Exports,  Inc.,  75  West  St.,  New  York 

American  Provisions  Export  Co.,  80  East  Jackson  Blvd., 

Chicago,  111. 
American  Soda  Pulp  Export  Association,  230  Park  Ave., 

New  York. 
American  Spring  Manufacturers  Export  Association,  30 

Church  St.,  New  York. 
American   Tire    Manufacturers   Export   Association,   30 

Church  St.,  New  York. 
California  Alkali  Export  Association,  530  West  6th  St., 

Los  Angeles,  Calif. 
California  Dried  Fruit  Export  Ass^iciation,  1  Drumm  St., 

San  Francisco,  Calif. 
California  Prune  Export  Association,  1  Drumm  St.,  San 

Francisco,  Calif. 
California  Rice  Exporters,  351  California  St.,  San  Fran- 
cisco, Calif. 

Carbon  Black  Export,  Inc.,  500  5th  Ave.,  New  York 

Cement  Export  Co.,  Inc.,  The,  150  Broadway,  New  York. 

Copper  Exporters,  Inc.,  50  Broadway,  New  York 

Dbuglas  Fir  Export  Co.,  Henry  Bldg.,   Seattle,  Wash 

Durex  Abrasives  Corporation,  63  Wall  St.,  New  York 

Electrical  Apparatus  Export  Association,   70    Pine  St., 

New  York. 
Electrical  Export  Corporation,  100  West  10th  St.,  Wil- 
mington, Del. 
Export  Screw  Association  of  the  United  States,  23  Acorn 

St.,  Providence,  R.  I. 
Florida    Hard    Rock    Phosphate    Export    Association, 

Savannah  Bank  &  Trust  Bldg.,  Savannah,  Ga. 

General  Milk  Co.,  Inc.,  19  Rector  St.,  New  York 

Goodyear  Tire   &  Rubber   Export  Co.,  The,   1144  East 

Market  St.,  Akron,  Ohio. 
International  Wood    Naval  Stores  Export   Corporation, 

Gulfport,  Miss. 
Metal  Lath  Export  Association,  The,  47  West  34th  St., 

New  York. 
Northwest   Dried   Fruit   Export   Association,   Title  and 

Trust  Bldg.,  Portland,  Oreg. 
Pacific  Forest  Industries,  Tacoma  Bldg.,  Tacoma,  Wash.. 
Pacific  Fresh  Fruit  Export  Association,  333  Pine  St.,  San 

Francisco,  Calif. 
Pencil  Industry  Export  Association    703  East  13th  St., 

New  York. 
Phosphate  Export  Association,  393  7th  Ave.,  New  York.. 

152 


ProducU 
Wooden  box  shooks. 

Hardwood  lumber.  • 

Paper  products. 
Meat  products. 

Soda  pulp. 

Railway  springs. 

Railway  tires. 

AlkaH. 

Dried  fruit. 

Dried  prunes. 

Rice. 

Carbon  black. 

Cement. 

Copper. 

Lumber,  fir,  etc. 

Abrasives. 

Electrical  apparatus 

Do. 

Screws. 

Phosphate,  hard  rock. 

Milk,  condensed. 
Rubber  products. 

Wood  naval  stores. 

Metal  lath. 

Dried  fruit. 

Plywood. 
Fresh  fruit. 

Pencils,  pens,  etc. 

Phosphate,  pebble. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  153 

Products 

Pipe  Fittings  and  Valve  Export  Association,  The,  1421     Pipe  fittings,  etc. 

Chestnut  St.,  Philadelphia,  Pa. 
Plate  Glass  Export  Corporation,  Grant  Bldg.,  Pittsburgh,     Plate  glass. 

Pa. 
Potash  Export  Association,  Inc.,  21  East  40th  St.,  New    Potash, 

York. 
Redwood  Export  Co.,  405  Montgomery  St.,  San  Fran-    Lumber,  redwood. 

Cisco,  Calif. 
Rice  Export  Association,  Queen  and  Crescent  Bldg.,  New     Rice. 

Orleans,  La. 
Rubber    Export    Association,  The,    19    Goodyear   Ave.,     Rubber  products. 

Akron,  Ohio. 
Shook    Exporters    Association,    2718    Pershing    Drive,     Barrel  shooks. 

Memphis,  Tenn. 
Signal   Export   Association,   420   Lexington   Ave.,    New    Railway  signals. 

York. 
Steel  Export  Association  of  America,  The,  75  West  St.,     Steel  products. 

New  York. 

Sugar  Export  Corporation,  120  Wall  St.,  New  York Sugar. 

Sulphur  Export  Corporation,  420  Lexington  Ave.,  New    Sulfur. 

York. 
Textile  Export  Association  of  the  United  States,  40  Worth     Textiles. 

St.,  New  York. 
United  States  Alkali  Export  Association,  Inc.,  11  Broad-     Alkali. 

way.  New  York. 
Walnut  Export  Sales  Co.,  Inc.,  12th  St.  and  Kaw  River,     Walnut  lumber. 

Kansas  City,  Kans. 
Walworth  International  Co.,  60  East  42d  St.,  New  York..  Pipe  fittings,  etc. 


EXHIBIT  3 

120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  ^  TO  DECEMBER  1939,^  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES  - 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Perlodif 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion* 


Alabama-Florida  Pitch  Pine  Export  Association, 
New  Orleans . 

Shipped  pitch-pine  lumber  and  timber  to  Latin- 
American  markets,  doing  a  substantial  busi 
ness  when  first  in  operation.  In  1932  it 
reported  a  lessening  of  exports  but  "despite 
depression  we  believe  the  advantages  of  our 
organization  are  many,  enabling  all  the  mills 
in  our  association  to  obtain  a  fair  share  of  the 
business  being  oflFered."  In  1933  conditions 
in  South  American  countries  made  operation 
impossible  and  the  association  was  dissolved. 

Members 

Alger-Sullivan  Lumber  Co.,  Century,  Fla 

Brown-Florida  Lumber  Co.,  Cary ville,  Fla 

Jackson  Lumber  Co.,  Lockhart,  Ala 

Pensacola  Lumber  &  Timber  Co.,  Pensacola, 

Fla 

St.  Andrews  Bay  Lumber  Co.,  Millville,  Fla... 
Swift  Hunter  Lumber  Co.,  Atmore,  Fla 

American  Box  Shook  Export  Association,   Wash- 
ington, D.  C 

Exports  wooden  shooks  to  foreign  countries. 
The  chief  advantage  reported  by  the  associa- 
tion is  the  pooling  of  information  and  elim- 
ination of  unnecessary  expense  in  exporting. 

Members 

American  Box  Corporation,  San  Francisco 

Barnes,  E.  H.,  Co.,  New  York 

Bloedel-Donovan  Lumber  Mills,  Seattle 

Clover  Valley  Lumber  Co.,  Loyalton,  Calif 

General  Box  Co.,  Chicago 

Lea,  David  M.,  &  Co.,  Richmond,  Va 

Lewis-Bean  Co. ,  Seattle 

McNeill,  Lauff  &  McNeill,  Thomson,  Ga 

Miller  Mfg.  Co.,  Richmond,  Va 


1929-33 
1929-33 
1929-33 

1929-33 
192^31 
1929-33 


1935-39 
1935-39 
1935-36 
1935-39 
1935-36 
1935-39 
1935-37 
1935-36 
1935-36 


1929-33 


13 


1935-39 


>  This  list  does  not  Include  a  number  of  companies  that  filed  paiwrs  under  misapprehension  during  the 
first  year  of  operation;  they  were  found  to  be  engaged  in  business  other  than  exporting,  and  were  dropped 
from  the  Commission's  list. 

*  Includes  also  the  Electrical  Export  Corporation  formed  in  January  1940,  and  some  changes  shown  In 
amiuaJ  reports,  January  1840. 

» The  period  of  operation  noted  here  dates  from  filing  of  papers  by  the  Commission,  and  not  from  organiza- 
tion date. 

154 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


155 


120  ASSOCIATIONS'  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


American  Box  Shook  Export  Association — Con. 

Neils,  J.,  Lumber  Co.,  Klickitat,  Wash 

New  England  Box  Co.,  Greenfield,  Mass 

New  Mexico  Box  &  Lumber  Co.,  Bernalillo, 

N.  Mex 

Weyerhaeuser  Sales  (^.,  Chicago 


Years 


American     Brake    Beam     Manufacturers    Export 


Shipped  brake  beams  for  railway  equipment  to 
foreign  countries.  The  association  reported 
that  "foreign  business  in  any  volume  would 
be  impossible  without  operating  as  an  asso- 
ciation." In  1929,  however,  it  was  found 
that  foreign  car  builders  bought  beams  made 
in  their  own  country,  and  replacement  orders 
on  American  equipment  usually  went  to  the 
company  that  originally  supplied  the  cars. 
The  two  member  companies  therefore  de- 
cided to  sell  individually,  and  dissolved  the 
association. 

Members 

American  Steel  Foundries,  Chicago 

Chicago  Railway  Equipment  Co.,  Chicago 


American  Corn  Products  Export  Association,  New 

York 

Formed  to  export  surplus  of  corn  sirup,  sugar, 
and  starch,  production  of  which  was  in- 
creased during  the  war.  The  association 
was  a  member  of  Grain  Products  Export 
Association,  also  formed  under  the  act.  It 
operated  successfully  for  several  years,  re- 
porting that  "the  centralization  of  statis- 
tical and  other  information  makes  possible 
an  intelligent  distribution  of  stocks,  accord- 
ing to  the  varying  needs  of  foreign  markets. 
The  quality  of  American  products  in  this  in- 
dustry has  been  raised  to  a  uniformly  higher 
level  as  the  result  of  the  necessity  of  regard- 
ing the  best  quality  of  goods  made  by  any 
member  as  the  standard  quality  to  be  pro- 
duced by  all.  The  facilities  provided  under 
the  Webb-Pomerene  Act  place  us  in  a  posi- 
tion to  combat  foreign  competition  in  a  way 
that  would  not  otherwise  be  possible." 
However,  the  association  was  seriously  af- 
fected by  increased  production  abroad  and 
tariff  barriers,  and  became  dissolved  in  1927. 

Members 

American  Maize  Products  Co.,  New  York 

American  Maize  Sales  Corporation,  New  York. 
Anheuser-Busch,  Inc.,  St.  Louis. _: 


1935-36 
1935-39* 

1935-36 
1935-39 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


1925-29 
1925-29 


1922-24 
1924-27 
1923-27 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


2    1925-29 


12 


1922-27 


156 


CX)NCE1NTRATI0N  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


American   Cotn    Products    Export  Association — 
Continued. 

Clinton  Corn  Syrup  Refining  Co.,  Clinton,  Iowa 

Hubinger,  J.  C,  Bros.  Co.,  Keokuk,  Iowa 

Huron  Milling  Co.,  Harbor  Beach,  Mich 

Keever  Starch  Co.,  Columbus,  Ohio 

Penick  &  Ford  Sales  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Piel  Bros.  Starch  Co.,  Indianapolis 

Staley,  A.  E.,  Manufacturing  Co.,  Decatur,  Ill- 
Union  Sales  Corporation,  Columbus,  Ind 

Union  Starch  &  Refining  Co.,  Edinburg,  Ind__. 

American  Export  Door  Corporation,  Tacoma,  Wash. 
Formed  to  ship  doors  to  foreign  markets,  the 
association  reported  successful  business,  an 
increase  in  export  demand  for  the  members' 
products,  and  "a  better  spirit  of  cooperation 
amongst  our  several  ma^ufar^turers,  together 
with  a  keener  appreciation  (  f  export  trade." 
However,  it  became  invol  ed  in  litigation 
with  one  of  its  members  {American  Export 
Door  Corp.  v.  John  A.  Ganger  Co.,  283  Pac. 
462)  and  was  dissolved  in  1930. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Buflfelen  Lumber  &  Manufacturing  Co.,  Ta- 
coma, Wash 

Clear  Fir  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Knox  &  Toombs,  Hoquiam,  Wash 

McCleary,  Henry,  Timber  Co.,  McCleary, 
Wash 

Nicolai  Door  Manufacturing  Co.,  Portland, 
Oreg -. 

Peterman  Manufacturing  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash.. 

Robinson  Manufacturing  Co.,  Everett,  Wash.. 

Tregoning  Manufacturing  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash.. 

Washington  Door  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Wheeler-Osgood  Co.,  The,  Tacoma,  Wash 

American  Export  Lumber  Corporation,  Philadelphia 
Formed  in  1919  by  members  of  the  National 
Bureau  of  Wholesale  Lumber  Distributors, 
Inc.,  to  ship  lumber  to  the  Allies  for  recon- 
struction of  areas  devastated  by  the  World 
War.  After  some  preliminary  work,  the 
corporation  canceled  its  charter  and  became 
dissolved  in  1920. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Aberdeen  Lumber  Co.,  Pittsburgh 

Allied  Sales  Corporation,  Tuscaloosa,  Ala 

American  Lumber  &  Manufacturing  Co.,  Pitts- 
burgh  

Anguera  Lumber  &  Tie  Co.,  Chicago 

Blanchard  Lumber  Co.,  Boston 


1922-27 
1922-27 
1922-27 
1922-27 
1922-27 
1922-27 
1922-25 
1924-27 
1922-24 


1927-30 
1927-30 
1927-30 

1927-30 

1927-30 
1927-30 
1928-30 
1927-29 
1927-30 
1927-30 


10 


1927-30 


51 


1919-20 


I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  J  57 

120  ASSOCIATIONS'  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  's  RADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Total  nuni' 

berof 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


American  Export  Lumber  Corporation^ContiDued 

Bruner,  Owen  M.,  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Cain  Hurley  Lumber  Co.,  St.  Louis,  Mo 

Chickasaw  Lumber  Co.,  Demopolis,  Ala 

Coale,  Thos.  E.,  Lumber  Co.,  Philadelphia.  _. 

Colby  &  Dickinson,  Inc.,  Seattle 

Coppock,  S.  &  P.,  &  Sons  Co.,  Ft.  Wayne,  Ind. 

Craig  Huff  Lumber  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Cross,  B.  W.,  Lumber  Co.,  Pittsburgh. 

Currie  &  Campbell,  Philadelphia 

Daley,  E.  H.,  Lumber  Co.,  New  York 

Danges,  J.  C,  Lumber  Co.,  Pittsburgh 

Davis,  Henry  D.,  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Oreg 

Dougherty  McKay  &  Co.,  Valdosta,  Ga 

Driver,  L.  F.,  &  Co.,  Thomasville,  Ga 

Duncan  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Oreg 

Eitzen  Touart  Co.,  Pensacola,  Fla 

Erie  Lumber  Co.,  Erie,  Pa 

Germain  Co.,  The,  Pittsburgh 

Godfrey,  L.  N.,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Hallowell  &  Souder,  Philadelphia 

Hammer,  Thomas  B.,  Philadelphia 

Herron,  Lawton,  Parks  Co.,  Seattle 

Hettler,  H.  H.,  Chicago 

Hirsch  Lumber  Co.,  New  York 

Houston  Lumber  Co.,  Thomasville,  Ga 

Jemison,  J.  B.,  &  Co.,  Thomasville,  Ga 

Kreamer  Lumber  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Levy,  A.  J.,  Lumber  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Mackintosh  &  Truman  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle 

Marsh  &  Truman  Lumber  Co.,  Chicago 

McLeod  Lumber  Co.,  Hattiesburg,  Miss 

McWiUiams  Lumber  Co.,  Mobile,  Ala 

Mickle,  Geo.  T.,  Chicago 

Rayner  &  Parker,  Philadelphia 

Ryland  &  Brooks  Lumber  Co.,  Baltimore 

Saari-Tully  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Oreg 

Sizer,  R.  B.,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Stitzinger,  G.  G.,  &  Co.,  New  Castle,  Pa 

Stoner,  E.  H.,  Pittsburgh 

Truman,  M.  G.,  Chicago 

Turnbull,  J.  W.,  Lumber  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Walker  Johnston  Lumber  Co.,  Mobile,  Ala 

Western  Lumber  Sales  Co.,  Seattle 

Wilson,  W.  A.,  &  Son,  Wheehng,  W.  Va _. 

Wistar,  Underhill  &  Nixon,  Philadelphia 

Wyatt  Prock  Lumber  Co.,  Philadelphia 


American  Hardwood  Exporters,  Inc.,  New  Orleans. 
Ships  hardwood  lumber  to  foreign  countries. 

Members  (stockholders) 


Anderson-Tully  Co.,  Memphis,  Tenn. 
Atlantic  Lumber  Co.,  Boston,  Mass.. 
Bruce,  E.  L.,  Co.,  Memphis,  Tenn 


1930-39 
1937-39 
1930-39 


1930-39 


158 


OONCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS'  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  niun 

ber  of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


American  Hardwood  Exporters,  Inc. — Continued. 

Chicago  Mill  &  Lumber  Co.,  Chicago 

Frost  Lumber  Industries,  Inc.,  Shreveport,  La. 

Gayoso  Lumber  Co.,  Memphis,  Tenn 

Hillyer  Deutsch  Edwards,  Inc.,  Oakdale,  La- 
Mobile  River  Saw  Mill  Co.,  Mt.  Vernon,  Ala- 
Pearl  River  Valley  Co.,  Hammond,  La 

American  Locomotive  Sales  Corporation,  New  York 
Sold  locomotives  and  spare  parts;  was  a  mem- 
ber of  the  Locomotive  Export  Association, 
cooperating  with  Baldwin  Locomotive  Works 
on  export  sales.  In  1939,  the  Sales  Corpo- 
ration advised  that  it  was  selling  only  for  the 
American  Locomotive  Co.,  and  was  therefore 
not  an  association;  withdrawing  from  opera- 
tion under  the  act. 

Members 


All  stock  held  by  the  American  Locomotive  Co. 

American    Maize    Products    Export    Association, 
Chicago 

Name  changed  to  United  States  Maize  Prod- 
ucts Export  Corporation  in  1920.  (See 
United  States  Maize.) 

American  Milk  Products  Corporation,  New  York-. 

Name  changed  to  General  Milk  Co.  in  1930. 

(See  General  Milk.) 

American  Paper  Exports,  Inc. ,  New  York 

Exports  paper  and  paper  boards  to  all  parts  of 
world;  in  successful  operation  since  1918. 


1930-39 

1939 

1930-32 

1939 

1939 

1934-37 


1919-39 


Members  {stockholders) 

Alpaugh,  E.  R.,  Jersey  City,  N.  J 

American  Realty  Co.,  New  York 

American  Writing  Paper  Co.,  Holyoke,  Mass.. 

Appleton  Coated  Paper  Co.,  Appleton,  Wis 

Berkshire  Loan  &  Trust  Co.,  Pittsfield,  Mass-. 

Beveridge  Paper  Co.,  Indianapolis,  Ind 

Bond,  D.  W.,  Philadelphia .-. 

Brown,  L.  L.,  Paper  Co.,  Adams,  Mass 

Brownville  Paper  Co.,  Brownville,  N.  Y 

Capelle,  Geo.  S.,  Jr.,  Philadelphia 

Caplin,  S.,  Brooklyn,  N.  Y 

Carmichael  &  Co.,  Ltd.,  Sydney,  Australia 

Chable,  Louis,  Ridgewood,  N.  J 

Chable,  Marcelina,  Trustee,  Ridgewood,  N.  J.. 
Champion  Coated  Paper  Co.,  Hamilton,  Ohio-. 
Chemical  Paper  Manufacturing  Co.,-  Holyoke, 

Mass 

Collins,  Grellet,  Philadelphia 

Continental  Paper  &  Bag  Co.,  New  York 


1920-22 
193&-39 
1918-24 
1918-39 
1923-25 
1919-24 
1922-24 
1918-39 
1918-24 
1918-39 
1918-26 
1918-26 
1918-35 
1918-26 
1919-25 

1918-29 
1918-24 
1933-37 


1919-39 


61 


1919 

1920-26 
1919-30 

1930-39 
1918-39 


I 


J 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


159 


120  ASSOCIATIONS'  FORMED  UNDEE  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


AmericRD  Paper  Exports,  Inc. — Continued. 

Crane  &  Co.,  Dalton,  Mass 

Crane,  Z.  &  W.  M.,  Dalton,  Mass 

Crocker- McElwain  Co.,  Holyoke,  Mass 

Detroit  Sulpiiite  Pulp  &  Paper  Co.,  Detroit 

Dexter  Sulphite  Pulp  &   Paper  Co.,   Dexter, 

N.  Y 

Dill  &  Collins  Co.,  Philadelphia. 

Franklin,  Benj.  A.,  Bridgeport,  Conn 

Hammermill  Paper  Co.,  Erie,  Pa 

Hastings,  Arthur  C,  New  York -. 

Hastings,  Helen  M.,  Devon,  Pa 

Holyoke  Card  &  Paper  Co.,  Springfield,  Mass.. 

Ideal  Coated  Paper  Co.,  Broolffiold,  Mass 

International  Paper  Co.,  New  York 

Kimberly-Clark  Corporation,  Neenah,  Wis 

LaBree,  Benj.,  Jr.,  New  York 

LaMonte,  Geo.,  &  Sons,  New  York 

Maratlion  Paper  Mills  Co.,  Rothschild,  Wis 

Marquardt,  O.  F.,  Philadelphia 

Martin-Cantine  Co.,  Saugerties,  N.  Y 

Mcintosh,  D.  F.,  Jersey  City,  N.  J 

Mt'I.auren-Jones  Co.,  Brookfield,  Mass 

Missisquoi  Pulp  &  Paper  Co.,  Sheldon  Springs, 

Vt 

Monroe  Binder  Board  Co.,  Monroe,  Mich 

Moses,  Horace  A.,  Mittineague,  Mass 

Mountain  Mill  Paper  Co 

Muniford  Paper  Mills,  Inc.,  Mumford,  N.  Y... 
Nashua  Gummed  &  Coated  Paper  Co.,  Nashua, 

N.  H 

Neuhauser,  E.  B.  D.,  Philadelphia 

New  York  &  Penn.  Co.,  New  York 

Parsons  Paper  Co.,  Holyoke,  Mass 

Richmond   Paper    Manufacturing   Co.,    Rich- 
mond, Va 

Rising,  B.  D.,  Paper  Co.,  Housatonic,  Mass 

Robertson,  E.  C,  Hinsdale,  N.  H 

Robertson,  W.  F.,  Hinsdale,  N.  H 

Sanburn,  W.  H.,  Mittineague,  Mass 

Stevenson,  Louis  T.,  Lee,  Mass 

Strathmore  Paper  Co..  Mittineague,  Mass 

Taylor,  H.  W.,  Philadelphia 

Ticonderoga  Pulp  &  Paper  Co.,  Ticonderoga, 

N.  Y -._ 

United  Paperboard  Co.,  New  York 

Ware  Paper  Co.,  Ware,  Mass _. 

West  Virginia  Pulp  &  Paper  Co.,  New  York 

York  Haven  Paper  Co.,  Philadelphia.  _ _ 


American  Pitch  Pine  Export  Co.,  New  Orleans. 

Sold  pitch  pine  lumber  and  timber,  as  export 
agent  for  its  stockholders  and  other  lumber 
mills;  also  bought  and  sold  on  its  own  ac- 
count; developed  a  hardwood  department 
in  1927,  selling  for  a  number  of  hardwood 


1918-39 
1919-26 
1918-35 
1919-24 

1918-23 
1918-19 
1918-26 
1918-34 
1918-26 
1922-25 
1918-24 
1919-22 
1918-39 
1918-39 
1919-24 
1920-29 
1919-24 
1922-24 
1918-35 
1918-39 
1922-25 

1919-27 

1919-24 

1918-26 

1918 

1920-35 

1919-24 
1922-24 
1918-26 
1918-39 

1918-35 
1918-39 
1919-25 
1919-25 
1918-26 
1920-26 
1918-26 
1922-26 

1918-35 
1918-39 
1919-22 
1918-39 
1919-33 


15 


1919-35 


160 


OONCENTRATION  OF  BOONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS'  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 

Total  num- 
ber of 
members 

Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 

American  Pitch  Pine  Export  Co. — Continued. 

mills;  and  also  in  1927  established  export 
connections  for  manufacturers  of  boxes  and 
box  shooks.   Operated  successfully  for  a  num- 
ber of  years,  reporting  that  through  the  ex- 
port association  "both  mill  and  buyer,  lilce- 
wise     agent    and     carrier,     enjoy     decided 
advantages."     However,  the  supply  of  long 
leaf  pine,  the  preferred  export  species,  be- 
came depleted,   and  some  of  the  member 
mills  stopped  cutting;  exchange  restrictions 
and  other  unfavorable  conditions  in  Latin 
American  markets  made  exportation  diffi- 
cult; and  the  association  became  dissolved  in 
1935. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Bentley  &  Emery 

1919-29 
1919-35 
1919-30 
191&-35 
1921-25 
1928-35 
191&-21 
1919-29 
1919-21 
1919-35 
191&-35 
191S-22 
1919-20 
1921-27 
1919-31 

Eastman,  Gardiner  &  Co 

Finkbine  Lumber  Co      

Great  Southern  Lumber  Co 

Green  Lumber  Co               

Kirby  Lumber  Co             -   - 

Lamar  Lumber  Co                    

Major-Sowers  Sawmill  Co       

Marathon  Lumber  Co                __   

Natalbany  Lumber  Co          .-   

Newman   J  J    Lumber  Co         

Robinson  Land  &  Lumber  Co        

Wausau-Southern  Lumber  Co        _   

White  Helen,  Lumber  Co               -   

White,  J.  J.,  Lumber  Co 

American  Producers  Export  Corporation  of  Dela- 
ware, New  York          

2 

1921-22 

Formed  in  1921  to  represent  groups  of  pro- 
ducers in  various  lines,  and  to  hold  the  stock 
of  the  American  Producers  Export  Corpora- 
tion of  New  York.     The  plan  was  not  suc- 
cessfully developed,  and  became  abandoned 
in  1922. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Samuels,  Harold  C,  New  York 

Guggenheimer,  Newton,  N.  Y. 

American  Producers  Export  Corporation  of  N.  Y., 
New  York    ___   

1 

1921-22 

Formed  in  1921  to  take  over  the  business  of  the 
Seaboard  Raw  Products  Co.,  and  to  repre- 
sent groups   of   producers  in  various  lines. 
The  plan  was  not  successfully  developed  and 
became  abandoned  in  1922.     All  stock  held 
by: 

American  Producers  Export  Corporation  of 
Delaware,  New  York 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


161 


120  ASSOCIATIONS'  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 

Total  num- 
ber of 
members 

Period  of 
assod* 
ation 
opera- 
tion 

American  Provisions  Export  Co.,  Chicago.-    -_ 

20 

16 

1919-39 

Exports    packing    house    products,    incUiding 
meats,  lard,  cured  pork  products,  oleos,  and 
white  grease,  reporting  a  saving  in  operating 
expense  due  to  combination  of  export  depart- 
ments of  members  in  one  association  export 
office. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Armour  &  Co.,  Chicago 

1927-39 

1919-26 

1919-31 

1924-27 

1919-39 

1919-39 

1919-39 

1932-34 

1919-25 

1919-24 

1919-25 

1927-34 

1919 

1919-25 

1928-39 

1934-39 

1919-31 

1919-31 

1927-39 

1927-39 

Boyd  Lunham  &  Co.,  Chicago   

Cleveland  Provision  Co.,  The,  Cleveland 

Decker,  Jacob  E.,  &  Sons,  Mason  City,  lowa.. 

Dold,  Jacob,  Packing  Co.,  Buffalo,  N.  Y 

Hammond  Standish  &  Co.,  Detroit 

Hormel,  Geo.  A.  &  Co.,  Austin,  Minn 

Hygrade  Food  Products  Co.,  Chicago 

Indianapolis  Abattoir  Co.,  Indianapolis 

Iowa  Packing  Co.,  Des  Moines,  Iowa .. 

Miller  &  Hart,  Chicago..        .                  

North  Packing  &  Provision  Co.,  Boston.. 

Parker  Webb  &  Co.,  Detroit 

Roberts  &  Cake,  Chicago 

Sinclair,  T.  M.,  &  Co.,  Ltd.,  Cedar  Rapids,  Iowa 
Squire,  John  P.,  Co.,  Chicago 

St.  Louis  Independent  Packing  Co.,  St.  Louis.. 

Sullivan  Packing  Co.,  Detroit 

Swift  &  Co.,  Chicago 

Wilson  &  Co.,  Chicago 

American  Rice  Export  Corporation,  Crowley,  La 

1927-33 

Formed  in  1927  to  purchase  rice  from  mills  and 
farmers  in  Louisiana  and  Texas,  and  export 
to  foreign  countries;  became  dormant,  but 
filed  papers  for  several  years,  reporting  that 
"during  our  active  period,  we  found  great 
advantage  would  accrue  from  the  consoli- 
dation of  export  sales  through  the  medium 
of  one  organization." 

Members  (stockholders) 

Boyt,  A.  H.,  Beaumont,  Tex 

1927-31 
1927-31 
1927-31 
1927-31 
1927-31 
1927-31 
1927-33 
1927-31 
1927-31 
1927-31 
1927-31 
1927-31 
1931-33 

Erwin,  M.  P.,  Lake  Charles,  La.  .   .         _     .. 

Farmers  Land  &  Canal  Co.,  Inc.,  Lake  Charles.. 

Gardiner  Plantation  Co.,  Inc.,  Lake  Charles 

Hollins,  A.,  Lake  Charles.     ..   .   _         

Houston  River  Canal  Co.,  Lake  Charles 

Kaplan,  A.,  Crowley,  La         

King,  Geo.  M.,  Lake  Charles 

Lacassine  Irrigation  Co.,  Jennings,  La 

La.  Irrigation  &  Mill  Co.,  Crowley,  La 

Prairie  Land  &  Canal  Co.,  Inc.,  Lake  Charles. . 

Sabine  Canal  Co.,  Lake  Charles 

Simon,  L.  M.,  Houston,  Tex ' 

162 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 

Total  num- 
ber of 
members 

Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
ation 

American  Rice  Export  Corporation — Continued. 
Southwest    Louisiana    Farm    Mortgage    Co., 
Lake  Charles. 

1927-31 
1927-31 
1927-31 

Sweetlake  Land  &  Oil  Co.,  Inc.,  Lake  Charles.  . 
Todd,  0.  J.,  Beaumont,  Tex 

American  Soda  Pulp  Export  Association,  New  York. 
The  association  handles  exports  of  bleached 
soda  pulp  for  the  member  companies;  quota- 
tions made  on  the  individual  brands.     The 
principal    advantage   reported   is   that   the 
members  can  sell  and  the  foreign  purchasers 
can  buy  througli  one  central  office. 

11 

1919-39 

Members 

Champion  Coated  Paper  Co.,  Hamilton,  Ohio.. 
Champion  Fibre  Co.,  Hamilton,  Ohio 

1919 

1920-22 

1919-29 

1921-23 

1919-27 

1919-22 

1922-25 

1919-39 

1919-39 

1919-22 

1919-23 

Columbian  Paper  Co.,  Philadelphia     .   

Dill   &   Collins,    Philadelphia 

Jessup  &  Moore  Paper  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Kingsport  Pulp  Corporation,  Kingsport,  Tenn.. 
Mead  Fibre  Co.,  Dayton,  Ohio       

New  York  &  Pennsylvania  Co.,  New  York 

Penobscot  Chemical  Fibre  Co.,  Boston 

Ticonderoga  Pulp  &  Paper  Co.,  Ticonderoga.  . 
Warren  S.  D.,  Co.,  Boston 

American  Soft  Wheat  Millers  Export  Corp.,  Wash- 
ington, D.  C 

41 

1927-34 

Organized  in  1927  to  sell  flour  for  export  to 
foreign  markets  through  a  sales  manager  in 
New  York,  the  association  reported  that  it 
"furnished  an  outlet  for  a  lot  of  the  soft 
wheat  flour  in  Maryland  and  Pennsylvania 
that  they  would  not  have  had  otherwise." 
It  prospered  until  1929  when  it  began  to  feel 
the  effects  of  increased  production  of  wheat 
and   flour  abroad,  under  governmental  en- 
couragement and  restrictions  placed  on  im- 
ports,  as  well  as  requirements  for  certain 
proportions  of  local  grain  to  be  used  in  mil- 
ling.    Foreign   demand  for  American  flour 
lessened    to    such    an  extent  that  the  cor- 
poration abandoned  its  business  in  1934. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Baruitz,  William  B.,  Carlisle,  Pa 

1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-34 
1927-34 
1927-33 

Beam,  W.  B.,  Camp  Hill,  Pa   

Bowman  Bros.,  Gaithersburg,  Md 

City  Flouring  Mills,  Muncy,  Pa 

Derwood  Mill,  Derwood,  Md 

Ecker,  A.  W.,  &  Son,  Thurmont,  Md 

Felix  &  Lindsav,  Newville,  Pa 

Felton  &  Kelly,  Frederick,  Md 

i 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


163 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


American  Soft  Wheat  Millers  Export  Corp. — Con. 

Flory  Bros.,  Lancaster,  Pa 

Franklin  Milling  Co.,  Middleburg,  Pa 

Frey  Bros.,  Salunge,  Pa 

Girvin,  W.  B.,  Leola,  Pa 

Hefty  Milling  Co.,  Watsontown,  Pa 

Heishman,  B.  F.,  Carlisle,  Pa 

Hershey,  S.  W.,  Flouring  Mills,  York,  Pa 

Hess,  A.  S.,  &  Son,  Kinzers,  Pa 

Hickerson  Bros.,  Rockville,  Md 

Hoffman,  W.  A.,  Chadds  Ford,  Pa 

Hunsecker,  H.  S.,  Willow  Street,  Pa 

Huntingdon  Milling  Co.,  Huntingdon,  Pa 

Jefferson  Milling  Co.,  Charles  Town,  W.  Va... 

Kline  Bros.,  Boonsboro,  Md 

Lakeview  Milling  Co.,  Chambersburg,  Pa 

Lancaster  Milling  Co.,  Lancaster,  Pa 

Lansdale,  R.  H.,  Sandy  Spring,  Md ' .-.. 

Liberty  Milling  Co.,  Germantown,  Md 

Patterson  Milling  Co.,  Saltsburg,  Pa 

Pennock,  J.  L.,  &  Co.,  Avondale,  Pa 

Pleasant  Valley  Roller  Mills,  W.  Leesport,  Pa. 

Pottstown  Roller  Mills,  Pottstown.  Pa 

Red  Bank  Mills,  New  Bethlehem,  Pa 

Rohrer,  Ross  H.,  Quarrvville,  Pa 

Round  Hill  Milling  Co..'  Round  Hill,  Va 

Routzahn,  C.  E.,  BreathedsviUe,  Md 

Sees  Milling  Co.,  Williamsport,  Pa 

Summit  Milling  Co.,  Gaithersburg,  Md 

Tyrone  Milling  Co.,  Tyrone,  Pa 

Wentzel,  H.  R.,  Landisburg,  Pa 

Wilkins-Rogers  Milling  Co.,  Washington,  D.  C. 

Willis,  C.  S.,  Leraovne,  Pa 

Willow  Bank  Roller  Mills,  Lititz,  Pa 


American  Spring   Manufacturers  Export   Associa- 
tion, New  York 

Sells  its  members'  products,  railway  steel 
springs,  in  foreign  markets.  It  reports  that 
"cooperation  between  the  various  members 
enables  the  cost  of  marketing  our  products 
abroad  to  be  distributed  among  all  of  the 
compai  'es,  and  likewise  enables  us  to  obtain 
and  have  available  at  one  centralized  point 
a  great  deal  of  foreign-trade  information 
that  is  quite  necessary  in  the  successful 
handling  of  an  export  business  sucli  as  this." 

Members 

American  Locomotive  Co.  (Railway  Steel 
Spring  Division),  New  York 

American  Spiral  Spring  &  Manufacturing  Co., 
Pittsburgh 

American  Steel  Foundries,  Chicago 

2.".7760— 41— No.  6 12 


1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-34 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-34 
1937-33 
1927-34 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1 927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 
1927-33 


1934-39 

1924-39 
1923-39 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1923-39 


164 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FOKMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num 

ber  of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


American  Spring  Manufacturers  Export  Associa- 
tion— Continued. 

Crucible  Steel  Co.  of  America,  New  York 

Fort  Pitt  Spring  &  Manufacturing  Co.,  Pitts- 
burgh   

Railway  Steel  Spring  Co.,  New  York.. 

Standard  Steel  Works  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Union  Spring  &  Manufacturing  Co.,  Pitts- 
burgh  -. 

American  Surface  Abrasives  Export  Corporation, 
New  York . 

Exported  abrasives  produced  by  the  member 
companies  from  1923  to  1931,  reporting 
"successful  promotion  of  foreign  business 
of  American  manufacturers,  and  more  or- 
derly and  economical  distribution  of  the 
export  product."  In  1930,  its  members 
formed  the  Durex  Abrasives  Corporation, 
which  is  still  in  operation  (see  Durex.) 

Members  {stockholders) 

American  Glue  Co.,  Boston 

Armour  &  Co.,  Chicago . 

Armour  Sand  Paper  Works,  Chicago 

Baeder  Adamson  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Barton,  H.  H.,  &  Son  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Behr,  Herman,  &  Co.,  Inc.,  Brooklyn 

Behr-Manning  Corporation,  Troy,  N.  Y 

Carborundum  Co.,  The,. Niagara  Falls,  N.  Y... 

Manning  Abrasives  Co.,  Troy,  N.  Y , 

Minnesota  Mining  &  Manufacturing  Co.,  St. 

Paul,  Minn 

U.  S.  Sand  Paper  Co.,  Williamsport,  Pa 

Wausau  Abrasives  Co.,  Wausau,  Wise 


American    Tanning    Materials    Corporation,    New 
York 

Organized  in  1919,  the  association  operated 
successfully,  disposing  of  surplus  tanning 
and  dyeing  extracts,  abroad,  until  a  lessen- 
ing of  foreign  demand  led  to  dissolution  of 
the  corporation  in  1923. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Andrews  Tanning  Extract  Co.,  Andrews,  N.  C. 

Brevard  Tannin  Co.,  Pisgah  Forest,  N.  C 

Chapipion  Fibre  Co.,  Canton,  N.  C 

Gardner  Extract  Co.,  Basic  City,  Va 

Grant  Leather  Co.,  Kingsport,  Tenn 

Heald,  J.  H.,  &  Co.,  Lynchburg,  Va 

Kingsport    Extract    Corporation,    Kingsport, 

Tenn 

Marion  Extract  Co.,  Marion,  Va 


1924-39 

1923-29 
1923-34 
1923-39 

1924-29 


1923-31 
1928-31 
1923-28 
1923-31 
1923-31 
1923-28 
1928-31 
1923-31 
1923-28 

1923-31 
1923-31 
1923-31 


1919-23 
1919-20 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1922-23 
1919-20 

1919-22 
1919-23 


12 


1923-31 


13 


1919-23 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


165 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


American  Tanning  Materials  Corporation — Con. 

Smethport  Extract  Co.,  Damascus,  Va 

Smoot,  C.  C,  &  Sons,  Alexandria,  Va 

Southern  Extract  Co.,  Knoxville,  Tenn 

Watauga  Extract  Co.,  Eliza bethton,  Tenn.. 
Young,  H.  E.,  &  Co.,  Charlottesville,  Va... 


1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 


American  Textile  Machinery  Corporation,  Boston.. 
Organized  in  1919  to  handle  export  sales  of  tex- 
tile machinery,  in  the  European  market,  the 
association  operated  successfully  reporting 
in  1922  a  saving  of  one- third  in  expenses 
through  consolidation  of  export  arrange- 
ments. Market  conditions  abroad,  how- 
ever, led  to  withdrawal  from  the  export  field 
of  some  of  the  members,  and  those  remain- 
ing decided  to  sell  individually.  The  asso- 
ciation was  therefore  dissolved  in  1925. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Crompton  &  Knowles  Loom  Works,  Worces- 
cester,  Mass 

Draper  Corporation,  Hopedale,  Mass.. 

Ketchum,  Phillips,  Boston 

Lockwood,  Greene  &  Co.,  Boston 

Saco-Lowell  Shops,  Boston 

Whitin  Machine  Works,  Whitinsville,  Mass 

American  Textile  Trading  Co.,  New  York 

Organized  in  1930  to  export  cotton  yarns  and 
goods,  the  association  operated  successfully 
until  affected  by  the  depression  and  political 
situation  in  Latin-American  markets,  and  by 
depreciated  currency  in  Europe,  which  les- 
sened the  volume  of  exports  and  led  to  dis- 
solution of  the  company  in  1934. 

Members 

Aberfoyle  Mfg.  Co.,  Philadelphia 

American  Yarn  &  Processing  Co.,  Mount  Holly, 
N.  C 

Dixie  Mercerizing  Co.,  Chattanooga,  Tenn 

Hampton  Co.,  The,  Easthampton,  Mass 

Spinners  Processing  Co.,  Charlotte,  N.  C 

Standard-Coosa-Thatcher  Co.,  Chattanooga, 
Tenn... 


1919-22 
1919-22 
1922-23 
1919-25 
1919-23 
1919-22 


1930-34 

1930-34 
1930-34 
1930-31 
1930-34 

1930-34 


American  Tire  Manufacturers  Export  Association, 
New  York 

Exports  railway  steel  tires,  reporting  that: 
The  association  makes  for  economy  in  work- 
ing as  a  single  unit  instead  of  having  a  sep- 
arate sales  organization  for  each  company 
and  has  been  an  advantage  to  the  members 
in  handling  of  shipping  documents  and  the 


1919-25 


1930-34 


1923-39 


166 


OONCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


American  Tire  Manufacturers  Export  Association — 
Continued. 

centralization  of  inquiries  and  orders.  It  not 
only  provides  for  dealing  more  effectively 
with  foreign  competition,  but  makes  possible 
better  service  to  the  customers,  splitting 
large  orders  among  two  or  three  members  of 
the  association  to  obtain  quicker  completion 
than  would  be  the  case  if  one  company  re- 
ceived the  entire  order." 

Members 

Chrome  Steel  Works,  Carteret,  N.  J 

Edgewater  Steel  Co.,  Pittsburgh 

Midvale  Co.,  The,  Philadelphia 

Midvale  Steel  &  Ordnance  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Railway  Steel  Spring  Co.,  New  York 

Railway   Steel   Spring   Division  of   American 

Locomotive  Co.,  New  York 

Standard  Steel  Works  Co.,  Burnham,  Pa 


Years 


American  Webbing  Manufacturers  Export  Assoc, 
New  York 

Formed  in  1919  to  export  elastic  and  non- 
elastic  webbing  manufactured  by  the  mem- 
ber companies,  the  association  developed  a 
profitable  business  abroad.  It  reported 
that:  "Perhaps  the  principal  advantage  in 
the  export  company  is  found  in  the  fact 
that  it  relieves  the  members  of  the  multi- 
tude of  details  peculiar  to  export  business, 
which  would  not  be  easy  for  them  to  handle 
owing  to  the  fact  that  the  factories  are  all 
in  the  interior.  There  is  a  great  advantage 
to  the  customer  whereby  he  is  enabled  to 
purchase  the  most  of  his  wants  or  require- 
ments in  this  line  from  one  source  *  *  * 
he  has  been  able  to  see  either  at  the  offices 
of  our  agents  in  the  several  countries,  or  at 
our  offices  in  New  York  if  he  came  here,  a 
very  complete  line  of  elastic  webbing  and 
other  articles,  whereas  he  would  have  to 
visit  many  places  to  see  the  same  merchan- 
dise in  our  members'  offices."  In  1932  the 
association  reported  losses  due  to  depression 
conditions,  the  exchange  situation,  and  the 
fact  that  lower  costs  abroad  made  it  impos-  • 
sible  to  compete  with  products  of  foreign 
competitors.  It  was  therefore  dissolved  in 
1932. 

Members 

American  Mills  Co.,  Waterbury,  Conn 

Ansonia  O.  &  C.  Co.,  Ansonia,  Conn 

Colton,  Geo.  S.,  Elastic  Web  Co.,  Easthampton, 
Mass _- 


1923-28 

1923-39 

1923-39 

1923 

1923-34 

1934-39 
1923-39 


Total  nuni' 

bcr  of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1919 
1919 

1919-28 


1919-32 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


167 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


American  Webbing  Manufacturers  Export  Assoc. — 
Continued. 

Conant,    Houghton    &    Co.,    Inc.,    Littleton, 

Mass --. 

Everlastik,  Inc.,  Chelsea,  Mass 

Rhode  Island  Textile  Co.,  ,Pawtucket,  R.  I_.. 

Sanford  Narrow  Fabric  Co.,  New  York 

Waterbury  Buckle  Co.,  Waterbury,  Conn 


Associated  Button  Exporters  of  America,  Inc.,  New 
York 

Formed  in  1921  to  include  a  number  of  button 
companies,  some  of  which  were  filing  sep- 
arately under  the  act;  the  association  estab- 
lished agencies  abroad  but  met  with  keen 
competition  from  foreign  manufacturers 
whose  production  costs  were  lower,  espe- 
cially the  Japanese  selling  in  Latin- American 
markets.  Sales  were  made  for  several  years, 
but  the  association  finally  became  dis- 
solved in  1933. 

Members  (stockholders) 

American  Pearl  Button  Co.,  Washington,  Iowa 
Automatic  Pearl  Button  Export  Co.,  Musca- 
tine, Iowa 

Clandere  Export  Corporation,  New  York . 

Davenport  Pearl  Button  Export  Co.,  Daven- 
port, Iowa 

Hampshire  Pearl  Button  Co.,  Amsterdam,  N.  Y. 
Hawkeye  Pearl  Button  Export  Co.,  Inc.,  Musca- 
tine, Iowa 

Howell,  Charles  M.,  Waltham,  Mass 

McKee-Bliven  Button  Co.,  Muscatine,  Iowa._- 
Mississippi  Pearl  Button  Co.,  Burlington,  Iowa. 
Nord-Buffum  Pearl  Button  Co.,  Louisiana,  Mo. 
Pioneer    Pearl    Button    Export    Co.,    Pough- 

keepsie,  N.  Y 

U.  S.  Button  Co.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

Wisconsin  Pearl  Button  Co.,  La  Crosse,  Wis 

Atlantic  &  Gulf  Export  Co.,  Jacksonville,  Fla 

This  association  filed  papers  in  1921,  with  in- 
tention of  exporting  naval  stores;  but  never 
came  into  operation.  Its  president,  W.  B. 
Gillican,  joined  the  Naval  Stores  Export 
Corporation,  formed  under  the  act  in  1923. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Aycock,  Thos.  J.,  Turpentine  Co.,  Loughridge, 
Fla 


Baldwin-Lewis  Co.,  Jacksonville 

Brooks-Scanlon  Corporation,  Biloxi,  Miss.. 
Bullard,  A.  F.,  De  Funiak  Springs,  Fla 


Years 


1919-28 

1919-28 

1919 

1919-28 

1919 


Total  num 

ber  of 
members 


1921-33 

1921-33 
1921-33 

1921-33 
1921-33 

1921-33 
1921-33 
1921-33 
1921-33 
1921-33 

1921-33 
1921-33 
1921-33 


13 


38 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1921-33 


1921 


168 


OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Total  nam' 

berof 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Atlantic  &  Gulf  Export  Co. — Continued. 

Coachman,  W.  F.,  Jacksonville 

Columbia  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Savannah 

Consolidated  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Jacksonville. .. 

Cranford,  J.  A.,  Jacksonville 

Darling,  A.  C,  Andalusia,  Ala --. 

Davis,  J.  B.,  &  Co.,  De  Funiak  Springs,  Flal.. 

Downing  Co.,  Brunswick,  Ga 

Fendig,  A.,  Brunswick,  Ga 

Fleishel,  M.  L.,  Jacksonville 

Flynn,  D.  M.,  Jacksonville 

Flynn-Harria-BuUard  Co.,  Jacksonville 

Foley,  J.  S.,  Eastport,  Fla .. 

Gay,  D.  J.,  Biloxi,  Miss 

Gillican,  W.  B.,  New  Orleans 

Gillican,  W.  B.,  agent.  New  Orleans 

Green,  Charle?,  Laurel,  Miss 

Guild,  W.  E.,  Jackson,  Miss 

Kelly,  W.  J.,  Jacksonville 

Knox,  L.  J.,  Mobile,  Ala 

Lewis,  J.  G.,  Jacksonville 

Mcintosh,  0.  T.,  Savannah 

Medlin,  J.  L.,  Jacksonville 

Nash,  J.  C,  Savannah 

Operators  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Jacksonville 

Peninsular  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Jacksonville 

Powell,  John  H.,  Jacksonville 

Putnam  Lumber  Co.,  Jacksonville 

Rose  and  Dasher,  Valdosta,  Ga 

Rose,  E.  P.,  Valdosta,  Ga 

Southern  States  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Savannah-. 

Taylor,  J.  A.,  New  Orleans _- 

Wade,  N.  G.,  Jacksonville 

Weibert,  H.,  Jacksonville-. — .- 

Williams  &  Rose,  Valdosta,  Ga 

Automatic  Pearl  Button  Export  Co.,  Inc.,  Musca- 
tine, Iowa 

Organized  to  handle  export  business  of  the 
Automatic  Button  Co.;  was  also  a  member 
of  the  Associated  Button  Exporters  of 
America,  Inc.,  filing  under  the  act.  Op- 
erated on  a  small  scale  for  several  years,  but 
found  it  impossible  to  compete  with  foreign 
producers,  and  therefore  dissolved  the  ex- 
port company  in  1929. 

Member^  (stockholders) 

Automatic  Pearl  Button  Co.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

Coates,  J.  H.,  Rowayton,  Conn  — 

Fack,  H.  H.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

Unlandt,  A.  M.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

Unlandt,  Carl  H.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

Unlandt,  Wm.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 


1921-29 


1921-29 
1921-25 
1921-29 
1927-29 
1925-29 
1921-29 


I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


169 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 

Total  num- 
ber of 
members 

Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 

California  Alkali  Export  Association,  Los  Angeles.  _ 

3 

54 

1936-39 

Ships  soda  ash  and  products  thereof  to  foreign 
countries,  cooperating  with  the  U.  S.  Alkali 
Export  Association,  an  older  group  operating 
under  the  act.     Among  other  advantages,  the 
association  reports  that  export  shipments  are 
so  distributed  "that  foreign  markets  are  not 
periodically  glutted  with  our  soda  ash  by 
too  much  tonnage  at  one  time." 

Members  (stockholders) 

American  Potash  &  Chemical  Corporation,  Los 
Angeles _-   

1936-39 
1936-39 
1936-39 

Pacific  Alkali  Co.,  Los  Angeles 

West  End  Chemical  Co.,  Oakland,  Calif 

California  Dried    Fruit    Export    Association,    San 
Francisco 

1925-39 

Ships  dried  fruits  to  foreign  markets,  reporting 
as  the  outstanding  advantages  of  association 
operation  "uniform  sales  terms  and  sound 
trade  customs"  in  export  trade,  the  associa- 
tion providing  for  inspection  and  certifica- 
tion of  goods  exported.     Its  membership  is 
divided  into  2  parts,  including  packers  and 
merchants: 

Packers'  Division 

Balfour-Guthrie  &  Co.,  Ltd.,  San  Francisco 

Barron-Gray  Packing  Co.,  San  Jose 

1932-39 
1925-29 
1928-39 
1925-39 

1925-39 
1933-39 
1925-29 
1934-39 
1929-39 
1925-30 
1925-39 
1925-32 
1925-37 
1928-39 
1928-35 
1929-34 
1925-27 
1925-39 
1926-28 
1925-39 
1925-39 
1925-27 
1937-39 

1930-39 
1933-38 

Bonner  Packing  Co. ,  Fresno .. 

California  Packing  Corporation,  San  Francisco. 
California  Prune  &  Apricot  Growers'  Associa- 
tion, San  Jose ..                   _____ 

ConsoUdated  Packing  Co.,  San  1?rancisco 

Coykendall,  Inc.,  Berkeley,  Calif.'      

Dick,  C.  L.,  &  Co.,  San.  Jose . 

El  Solyo  Ranch,  Vernalis,  Calif 

Garcia  &  Maggini  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Guggenhime  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Harlan,  0.  A.,  &  Co.,  San  Jose 

Herbert,  Geo.  N.,  Inc.,  San  Jose.      

Horst,  E.  Clemens,  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Inderrieden,  J.  B.,  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Jenks,  W.  T.,  Co.,  Inc.,  San  Jose       

Malaga  Packing  Co.,  Fresno 

Napa  Fruit  Co.,  Napa,  Calif                  __     

Pacific  Coast  Canners,  Inc.,  Oakland 

Richmond-Chase  Co.,  San  Jose                  .   _   ._ 

Rosenberg  Bros.  &  Co.,  San  Francisco __ 

Smith-Frank  Packing  Co.,  Sacramento 

Turlock  Dehydrating    &    Packing    Gp.,    Inc., 

Turlock,  Calif. 
Warren  Dried  Fruit  Co.,  San  Jose 

Wilbur-Ellis  Co.,  San  Francisco 

170 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 

Total  num- 
ber of 
memben 

Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 

California  Dried  Fruit  Export  Association — Con, 
Merchants  Division 
Abeling,  Geo. ,  Co. ,  San  Francisco 

1929-39 

1939 

1928-39 

1925-32 

1926-27 

1938-39 

1925-38 

1926-27 

1925-33 

1929-34 

1929-39 

1925-39 

1925-30 

1939 

1935-39 

1925-39 

1925-32 

1927-29 

1926-32 

1925-39 

1928-39 

1928-32 

1925-37 

1939 

1925-29 

1926-32 

1927-33 

1930-33 

1939 

7 

Andersen,  F.  E.,  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Atkins  Kroll  &  Co.,  Inc.,  San  Francisco 

Balfour-Guthrie  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Beesemyer- Waggoner,  Inc.,  Los  Angeles 

Berelson,  D.  B.,  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

California  Fruit  Selling  Co.,  San  Franci.sco 

California  Pacific  Mer.  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Catz  American  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Eyre,  Edward  L.,  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Feibusch,  M.,  San  Francisco 

Field,  Walter  M.,  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

General  Commercial  Co.,  Ltd.,  San  Francisco. 
Geron,  Geo.  A.,  San  Francisco. 

Gomperts,  Jack,  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Hall,  Harry,  &  Co.,  Inc.,  San  Francisco 

Newhall,  H.  M.,  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

O'Malley- Abeling  Co.,  San  Francisco 

O'Neill,  Eugene  M.,  San  Francisco 

Otis,  McAllister  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Parrott  &  Co. ,  San  Francisco 

Peabody,  Henry  W.,  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Schuckl  &  Co.,  San  Francisco. 

Sievers,  Paul  F.  L.,  San  Francisco 

Smillie,  Chas.  F.,  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Stahlbaum,  Rolf,  San  Francisco             -   

Waggoner,  Norman  L.,  Inc.,  San  Francisco 

Wilbur-Ellis  Co.,  San  Francisco..           

Wileman  Bros.  &  Elliott,  San  Francisco 

California  Prune  Export  Association,  San  Francisco. 

1936-39 

Organized  in  1936,  to  meet  special  conditions 
in  the  prune  export  trade,  the  first  agreement 
was  limited  to  a  3-month  period,  but  was 
thereafter  extended   to   20   years;  and  the 
association   has   served   when    needed.     Its 
members  are,  with  one  exception,  members  of 
the  California  Dried  Fruit  Export  Associa- 
tion, and  the  two  associations  have  the  same 
secretary. 

Members 

California  Packing  Corp.,  San  Francisco 

California  Prune  &  Apricot  Growers  Assoc, 
San  Jose                                    

1936-39 

1936-39 
1936-39 
1936-39 
1936-39 
1936-39 

1938-39 

Guggenheim  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Libby,  McNeil  &  Libby,  San  Francisco 

Richmond-Chase  Co.,  San  Jose   

Rosenberg  Bros.  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Warren  Dried  Fruit  Co.   (associate  member) 
San  Jose 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


171 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num 

ber  of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


California  Rice  Exportets,  San  FraftciBco. _. 

Organized  in  1939  to  export  rice  and  rice  prod- 
ucts to  foreign  markets. 

Members 

Capital  Rice  Mills,  San  Francisco 

Grosjean,  C.  E.,  Rice  Milling  Co.,  San  Fran- 
cisco   

Rice  Growers  Assoc,  of  Cal.,  Sacramento 

Rosenberg  Bros.  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Woodland  Rice  Co.,  Woodland,  Calif 


1939 


California  Sardine  Export  Association,  San  Fran- 
cisco  

Organized  in  1928,  the  association  did  some 
work  toward  development  of  export  trade, 
placing  members  in  contact  with  new  mar- 
kets and  buyers,  furnishing  information  on 
export  markets,  and  entering  into  agree- 
ments for  standardization  of  the  pack.  But 
thefe  was  a  serious  break  in  price  in  1929, 
some  members  were  unwilling  to  sell  at  lower 
prices,  and  the  association  became  inopera- 
tive, filing  no  reports  after  1930. 

Members 

Booth,  F.  E.,  Co.,  Inc.,  San  Francisco 

California  Packing  Corporation,  San  Francisco. 

Carmel  Canning  Co.,  San  Francisco. 

Coast  Fishing  Co.,  Wilmington,  Calif 

Del     Mar    Canning   Corporation,    Monterey, 

Calif 

Fran  CO- Italian  Packing  Co.,  Terminal  Island, 

Calif... 

French  Sardine  Co.,   Inc.,   Terminal   Island, 

Calif 

General  Fisheries  Corporation,  San  Pedro,  Calif. 

Gross,  E.  B.,  Canning  Co.,  Monterey,  Calif 

Hovden,  K.,  Co.,  Monterey,  Calif 

Italian  Food  Products  Co.,  Long  Beach,  Calif.. 
Kittle-Joerissen  Canning  Co.,  Terminal  Island. 
Linde  Packing  Corporation,  Terminal  Island, 

Calif.. 

L.  A.  Sea  Food  Packing  Co.,  Terminal  Island, 

Calif 

Monterey  Canning  Co.,  Monterey,  Calif 

San  Carlos  Canning  Co.,  Monterey,  Calif 

San  Xavier  Fish  Packing  Co.,  San  Francisco... 

Sea  Pride  Canning  Co.,  Monterey,  Calif 

Southern  California  Fish  Cor^ioration,  Terminal 

Island,  Calif 

Stafford  Packing  Co.,  Wilmington,  Calif 

Toyo  Fisheries  Co.,  Inc.,  Wilmington,  Calif 

Van    Camp    Sea    Food    Co.,    Inc.,    Terminal 

Island,  Calif 

Wedum  Packing  Co.,  Wilmington,  Calif... 


23 


1928-30 


1928-30 
1928-29 
1928-30 
1928-29 

1929-30 

1928-30 

1928-30 
1929-30 
1928-30 
1928-30 
1928-30 
1928 

1929-30 

1928 

1928-30 

1928-29 

1928-29 

1928-30 

1928-30 

1928 

1928 

1928-30 
1928-29 


172 


C?ONCBNTBATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FOKMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  c{ 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Canned  Foods  Export  Corporation,  Washington, 
D.  C 

Organized  in  1919  to  export  canned  foods,  the 
corporation  maintained  an  oflSce  with  the 
National  Canners  Association,  and  invited 
members  of  the  canners  association  to  join 
and  subscribe  to  stock.  Not  suflBcient 
interest  was  shown,  and  no  business  was 
transacted.  The  corporation  filed  papers 
until  1923,  then  became  dissolved. 

Organizers  were — 

Baines,  John  R.,  Baltimore,  Md. 
Polk,  Ralph  B.,  Greenwood,  Ind. 
.  Shriver,  Jos.  N.,  Westminster,  Md. 

Stock  was  issued  to — 

Nardin,  Wm.  T.,  St.  Louis,  Mo.,  (Mr.  Nardin 
became  vice  president  of  uhe  American  Milk 
Products  Corporation,  now  operating  under 
the  act  as  the  General  Milk  Co.,  Inc.). 

Carbon  Black  Export  Association,  Inc.,  New  York.. 
Operating  from  1929  to  1933  under  depression 
conditions,  the  association  reported  that 
"by  acting  in  concert,  members  were  able  to 
(  stablish  safeguards  in  connection  with  trade 
in  such  foreign  countries  where  currencies 
were  unstable  and  exchange  transactions 
extremely  difficult."  In  1933  the  associa- 
tion became  dissolved,  and  in  1934  four  of 
the  member  companies  joined  with  others  to 
form  the  Carbon  Black  Export,  Inc.,  under 
the  act. 


Members  (stockholders) 

Binney  &  Smith  Co.,  New- York 

Cabot,  Godfrey  L.,  Inc.,  Boston 

GreeflF,  R.  W.,  &  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York.. 

Huber,  J.  M.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Palmer     Gas     Products     Corporation, 

Chicago 

United  Carbon  Co.,  Charleston,  W.  Va.. 
Wishnick-Tumpeer,  Inc.,  New  York 


The, 


Carbon  Black  Export,  Inc.,  New  York 

Ships  carbon  black  to  foreign  countries.  Among 
other  advantages,  it  is  reported  that  cen- 
tralized operation  of  the  association  has 
enabled  the  members  to  share  the  risks  in 
exportation  during  the  depression  period. 
Membership  includes  some  of  the  companies 
that  held  stock  in  the  Carbon  Black  Export 
Association,  Inc.,  as  well  as  others. 


1929-33 
1929-32 
1929-33 
1929-33 

1929-33 
1929-33 
1932-33 


4  1919-23 


1929-33 


1935-39 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


173 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  nuni' 

berof 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Carbon  Black  Export,  Inc. — Continued. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Cabut,  Godfrey  L.,  Inc.,  Boston 

Century  Carbon  Co.,  New  York 

Columbia  Carbon  Co.,  New  York 

Huber,  J.  M.,  Corporation,  New  York ^... 

Johnson,  Chas.  Eneu.  &   Co.,  Philadelphia 

Palmer  Carbon  Co.,  The,  Chicago 

Panhandle  Carbon  Co.,  New  York 

Texas  Carbon  Industries,  Inc.,  Sayre,  Okla... 
United  Carbon  Co.,  Inc.,  Charleston,  W.  Va._. 

Carolina  Wood  Export  Corporation,  Norfolk,  Va._. 
Organized  in  1919  to  ship  lumber  and  wood 
products  to  foreign  countries;  the  association 
reported  in  1920  that- it  was  unable  to  carry 
on  business  due  to  the  prevailing  rates  of  ex- 
change and  depressed  conditions  in  foreign 
lumber  markets.  The  business  was  liqui- 
dated in  1923. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Adams  &  Graham,  Hamlet,  N.  C 

Burton,  E.  P.,  Lumber  Co.,  Charleston,  S.  C. 

Camp  Manufacturing  Co.,  Franklin,  Va 

Eureka  Lumber  Co.,  Washington,  N.  C 

Fosburgh  Lumber  Co.,  Norfolk,  Va 

Home  Building  &  Material  Co.,  The,  Asheboro, 

N.  C 

Jennings,  J.  F.,  Bamberg,  S.  C 

Marion  County  Lumber  Corporation,  Frank- 
lin, Va 

Montgomery  Lumber  Co.,  Suffolk,  Va 

Nichols,  W.  S.,  South  Boston,  Va 

Roper,  John  L.,  Lumber  Co.,  Norfolk,  Va 

Rowland  Lumber  Co.,  Norfolk,  Va 

South  Atlantic  Lumber  Co.,  Greensboro,  N.  C. 
Tuxbury,  A.  C,  Lumber  Co.,  Charleston,  S.  C. 

Cement  Export  Co.,  The,  Philadelphia  and  New 
York 

Organized  in  1919  to  ship  cement  to  foreign 
countries,  the  company  operated  for  about  2 
years,  then  reported  inactivity  due  to  the 
fact  that  export  business  could  not  be  carried 
on  profitably,  and  that  the  increasing  de- 
mand for  cement  in  this  country  had  made 
export  sales  unattractive.  The  company  has 
not  become  dissolved,  and  continues  to  file 
reports  with  the  Commission. 


1935-39 

1935-36 

1935-39 

1935-39 

1936-39 

1935 

1935-39 

1935-36 

1935-39 


1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 

1919-23 
1919-23 

1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 


14 


15 


1919-23 


1919-39 


274  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Cement  Export  Co.,  The — Continued. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Allentown  Portland  Cement  Co.,  Allentown, 
Pa . 

Dexter  Portland  Cement  Co.,  Nazareth,  Pa 

Giant  Portland  Cement  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Glens  Falls  Portland  Cement  Co.,  Glens  Falls, 

N.  Y 

Helderberg  Cement  Co.,  Albany,  N.  Y 

Hercules  Cement  Corporation,  Philadelphia 

Knickerbocker    Portland    Cement    Co.,    New 

York 

Lawrence  Portland  Cement  Co.,  New  York 

Lone  Star  Cement  Co.  of  New  York,  New  York. 
Lone  Star  Cement  Co.  of  Pennsylvania,  New 

York 

Nazareth  Cement  Co.,  Nazareth,  Pa - 

North  Americafl.. Cement  Co.,  AlUany,  N.  Y  — 

Pennsylvania  Cement  Co.,''New  York 

Pennsylvania  Dixie  Cement  Co.,  New  York 

Phoenix  Portland  Cement  Co.,  Philadelphia  — 

Chalmers,   Harvey,    &   Son    Export    Corporation, 
Amsterdam,  N.  Y 

Organized  in  1919  to  export  buttons  and  button 
materials  manufactured  by  Harvey  Chalmers 
&  Son  and  by  the  Hampshire  Pearl  Button 
Co.,  the  association  found  that  competition 
of  foreign  producers,  especially  Japanese, 
made  it  impossible  to  export  profitably.  It 
filed  papers  under  the  act  until  1931,  then 
become  dissolved. 

All  stock  held  by — 

Hampshire  Pearl  Button  Co.,  Amsterdam, 
N.  Y.,  which  was  also  a  member  of  Asso- 
ciated Button  Exporters  of  America,  Inc. 
(operating  under  the  act) . 

Clandere  Export  Corporation,  New  York 

Organized  in  1921  to  take  over  the  export 
business  of  Leo  H.  Hirsch  &  Co.,  the  corpor- 
ation was  also  a  member  of  Associated 
Button  Exporters  of  America  (operating 
under  the  act).  In  1923  it  reported  that  the 
condition  of  the  European  markets  was  such 
as  to  make  it  impossible  to  do  export  busi- 
ness; the  corporation  was  therefore  dis- 
solved. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Goldfrank,  Lionel,  New  York 

Hirsch,  Leo  H.,  New  York 

Joseph,  J.  S.,  New  York 


1919-39 
1919-33 
1919-39 

1919-39 
1919-33 
1919-39 

1919-33 
1919-39 
1933-39 

1933-39 
1919-39 
1933-39 
1919-33 
1933-39 
1919-33 


1921-23 
1921-23 
1921-23 


1921-31 


1921-23 


I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


175 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Period  of 
Total  num-     associ- 
ber  of  ation 

members       opera- 
tion 


Consolidated  Steel  Corporation,  New  York 

Organized  in  1919  to  export  iron  and  steel 
products,  the  corporation  established  agen- 
cies abroad  and  did  a  substantial  business 
for  several  years,  reporting  in  1922  that  "We 
consider  that  we  have  achieved  a  more  dis- 
tinct success  by  acting  under  the  Webb- 
Pomerene  law,  than  our  member  companies 
could  have  had  individually  *  *  *  tiiere 
can  be  no  doubt  that  ea'^h  of  the  companies 
that  we  represent  has,  by  selling  through  us, 
done  so  at  a  lower  cost  than  it  could  have  by 
selling  independently.  Selhng  to  export 
comprises  a  number  of  operations  which  do 
not  always  obtain  in  domestic  selling,  such 
as  the  problems  of  ocean  transportation  and 
insurance,  foreign  credits  and  collections, 
special  invoicing,  packing  and  marking. 
Certainly  no  one  of  our  member  companies 
could  maintain  foreign  agencies  individually, 
as  economically  as  we  maintain  them,  acting 
for  all."  The  association  became  dissolved 
in  1923,  but  some  of  its  members  joined  the 
Steel  Export  Association  of  America,  which 
was  organized  under  the  act  in  1928. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Bethlehem  Steel  Co.,  South  Bethlehem,  Pa 

Brier  Hill  Steel  Co.,  The,  Youngstown,  Ohio 

Cambria  Steel  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Lackawanna  Steel  Co.,  Buffalo,  N.  Y 

Lukens  Steel  Co.,  Coatesville,  Pa 

Midvale  Steel  &  Ordnance  Co.,  New  York 

Republic  Iron  &  Steel  Co.,  New  York 

Sharon  Steel  Hoop  Co.,  Sharon,  Pa 

Trumbull  Steel  Co.,  The,  Warren,  Ohio 

Whitaker-GIessner  Co.,  Wheeling,  W.  Va 

Youngstown  Sheet  &  Tube  Co.,  Youngstown, 
Ohio 


Copper  Export  Association,  New  York 

Organized  in  1919  to  export  copper  (all  unman- 
ufactured metallic  copper)  the  association 
served  as  selling  agent  for  its  members  and 
did  a  substantial  business.  In  1924  a  num- 
ber of  its  members  resigned.  In  1926  some 
of  its  members  joined  the  newly  formed  Cop- 
per Exporters,  Inc.  (under  the  act),  but  re- 
tained also  their  membership  in  Copper  Ex- 
port Association.  In  1933  the  certificate 
of  incorporation  was  amended  to  include 
business  other  than  export,  and  the  associa- 
tion therefore  withdrew  from  operation  under 
the  Export  Trade  Act. 


1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-21 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 
1919-23 

1919-23 


11 


1919-23 


27 


1919-33 


176 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FOKMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 

Total  num- 
ber of 
members 

Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 

Copper  Export  Association — Continued. 

Members  (stockholders) 

American  Smelting  &  Refining  Co.,  New  York. 

Anaconda  Copper  Mining  Co.,  New  York 

Arizona  Copper  Co.,  Clifton,  Ariz 

Calumet  &  Arizona  Mining  Co.,  Calumet,  Mich. 
Calumet  &  Hecla  Mining  Co.,  Boston 

1919-24 
1919-33 
1919-24 
1919-24 
1919-32 
1919-26 
1919-26 
1919-33 
1922-24 

1919-33 
1919-33 
1919-24 
1919-21 
1919-20 
1922-24 
1919-24 
1919-31 
1919-22 
1919-26 
1919-24 
1919-26 
1919-20 
1919-33 
1919-32 

1919-32 
1919-24 
1919-26 

19 

Chino  Copper  Co.,  New  York 

Consolidated  Coppermines  Co.,  New  York 

Greene  Cananea  Copper  Co.,  New  York 

Guggenheim  Bros.,  New  York 

Inspiration    ConsoHdated    Copper    Co.,    New 
York 

International  Smelting  Co.,  New  York 

Kennecott  Copper  Corporation,  New  York 

Lewisohn,  Adolph,  &  Sons,  New  York 

Miami  Copper  Co.,  New  York 

Mother  Lode  Coalition  Mines,  New  York 

Nevada  Consolidated  Copper  Co.,  New  York.. 

New  Cornelia  Copper  Co.,  Calumet,  Mich 

Nichols  Copper  Co.,  New  York      .    .          .    . 

North  Butte  Mining  Co.,  New  York     _    .    . 

Phelps  Dodge  Corporation,  New  York 

Ray  Consolidated  Copper  Co.,  New  York 

Tennessee  Copper  Co.,  New  York 

United  Metals  Selling  Co.,  New  York 

United  Verde  Copper  Co.,  New  York           _   _. 

United  States  Smelting,  Refining  &  Mining  Co., 
New  York.. __          .    

Utah  Copper  Co.,  New  York 

Utah  Consolidated  Mining  Co.,  New  York 

Copper  Exporters,  Inc.,  New  York . 

1926-39 

Organized  in  1926,  for  exportation  of  copper 
and  copper  products  to  foreign  markets,  the 
company    included    some    members    of    the 
Copper  Export  Association.     The  company 
had  a  substantial  business  until  1933,  when 
a  number  of  members  withdrew.     Reports 
are  still  sent  to  the  Commission,  but  the  com- 
pany is  at  present  inactive. 

Members  (stockholders) 

American  Metal  Co.,  Ltd.,  The,  New  York 

American  Smelting  &  Refining  Co.,  New  York.. 

Anaconda  Copper  Mining  Co.,  New  York 

Cajumet  &  Arizona  Mining  Co.,  Calumet,  Mich. 
Calumet  &  Hecla  Consolidated  Copper  Co., 
Boston _.                . 

1926-33 
1926-33 
1926-39 
1926-31 

1926-33 
1926-33 

] 926-39 
1926-33 

Copper  Range  Co.,  New  York 

Inspiration    Consolidated    Copper    Co.,    New 
York 

International  Metal  Co..  New  York 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


177 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Copper  Exporters,  Inc. — Continued. 

International  Minerals  &  Metals  Corporation, 

New  York 

Kennecott  Copper  Corporation,  New  York 

Mother  Lode  Coalition  Mines  Co.,  New  York. 
Nevada  Consolidated  Copper  Co.,  New  York_ 

New  Cornelia  Copper  Co.,  Calumet,  Mich 

Nichols  Copper  Co.,  New  York 

Old  Dominion  Co.,  Boston 

Phelps  Dodge  Corporation,  New  York 

Todd,  W.  Parsons,  Inc.,  New  York 

United  Verde  Copper  Co.,  New  York 

Utah  Copper  Co.,  New  York 


Davenport  Pearl  Button  Export  Co.,  Davenport, 
Iowa 

Organized  in  1921  to  take  over  the  export  busi- 
ness of  the  Davenport  Pearl  Button  Co.,  the 
export  company  was  also  a  member  of  the 
Associated  Button  Exporters  of  America, 
Inc.  (operating  under  the  act).  Exportation 
was  found  to  be  unprofitable,  due  to  foreign 
competition,  especially  Japanese.  Papers 
were  filed  for  a  number  of  years,  until  the 
company  was  dissolved  in  1931. 

All  stock  held  by — 

Davenport  Pearl  Button  Co.,  Davenport,  Iowa. 

Delta     Export     Lumber     Corporation,     Memphis, 
Tenn 

Organized  in  1922  to  export  red-gum  forest 
products  (lumber  and  logs),  the  company 
operated  successfully  for  several  years.  It 
reported  that  "we  are  thoroughly  convinced 
that  an  association  such  as  our  own  is 
equipped  to  handle  foreign  business  more 
efficiently  than  could  possibly  be  done  by 
any  individual  or  firm.  In  our  opinion,  the 
outstanding  advantages  obtained  by  the 
operation  of  this  corporation  are  the  ability 
to  collectively  maintain  offices  in  the  foreign 
markets,  and  securing  a  sufficient  volume  of 
business  to  hold  the  percentage  of  operating 
cogf  to  a  reasonable  figure,  and  such  a  plan 
would  be  impossible  for  the  small  individual 
operator;  to  push  sales  of  products  for  ex- 
port, through  a  joint  foreign-selling  office;  to 
standardize  grades  and  quality  under  regis- 
tered brands;  to  fix  definite  and  reasonable 
terms  of  payment;  to  provide  for  the  prompt 
and  fair  adjustment  of  claims  on  shipments; 
to  deal  effectively  with  the  railroad  and 
steamship  lines,  freight  rates,  and  on  matters 
of  port  and  dock  facilities;  and  the  loading 
and  discharging  of  cargo.     Practically  all  of 


1926-32 
1926-33 
1926-33 
1926-33 
1926-29 
1926-39 
1926-33 
1926-33 
1927-33 
1926-33 
1926-33 


1  1921-31 


31 


1922-26 


178  OONCBNTRATION  OF  EX^ON'OMIO  POWER 

120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Delta  Export  Lumber  Corporation — Continued. 

these  features  can  be  handled  more  effec- 
tively by  a  large  organization,  with  a  large 
volume,  than  they  could  possibly  be  handled 
with  small  individual  operators,  unorganized 
and  each  with  small  volume.  By  having  a 
direct  representative  and  office  in  the  foreign 
markets,  we  have  been  able  to  develop  an  in- 
creased consumption  of  certain  species  of  our 
forest  products,  showing  the  consumer  that 
certain  of  the  products  which  we  manufacture 
are  better  suited  to  his  needs  than  foreign 
woods  that  he  has  been  using;  and  this  has 
resulted  in  an  increased  demand  for  our 
woods.  *  *  *  Collectively  we  are  enabled 
to  keep  a  representative  in  the  foreign  market 
to  promptly,  fairly,  and  equitably  adjust 
claims  and  settle  disputes  whejQ  they  arise. 
We  find  that  by  having  our  representative 
available,  the  percentage  of  claims  made  and 
the  cost  of  adjusting  them  is  very  small. 
Fuither,  we  are  able  to  make  firm  sales  and 
arrange  terms  of  payment  for  full  amount 
of  our  invoices  when  goods  go  forward, 
because  the  reliable  and  reputable  foreign 
broker  and  foreign  importers  know  they  are 
dealing  with  a  responsible  organization,  with 
a  local  representative  available,  and  that  if 
goods  arrive  not  fully  up  to  specifications  or 
damaged  in  transit,  that  any  legitimate  and 
proper  claim  will  be  promptly  and  equitably 
adjusted." 

In  1926  low  prices  abroad  and  keen  com- 
petition from  mills,  with  shorter  and  less  ex- 
pensive freight  haul,  made  exportation  un- 
profitable; the  corporation  was,  therefore, 
dissolved. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Anderson  Tully  Co.,  Memphis,  Tenn 

Archer  Lumber  Co.,  Helena,  Ark 

Barr  Holaday  Lumber  Co.,  Greenfield,  Ohio.. 
Bayou  Land  &  Lumber  Co.,  Memphis,  Tenn.. 

Brown,  Geo.  C,  &  Co.,  Memphis,  Tenn 

Brown,  Mark  H.,  Lumber  Co.,  Lake  Providence 

La 

Brown,  W.  P.,  &  Sons  Lumber  Co.,  Louisville, 

Ky 

Brown  &  Hackney,  Memphis,  Tenn 

Carrier  Lumber  &  Manufacturing  Co.,  Sardis, 

Miss 

Chapman  &   Dewey   Lumber  Co.,    Memphis, 

Tenn 

Chess  &  Wymond  Co.,  Louisville,  Ky 

Chicago  Mill  &  Lumber  Co.,  Chicago 


1922-26 
1922-25 
1922-26 
1922-26 
1922-26 

1922-26 

1922-26 
1922 

1922-26 

1922-26 
1924-26 
1925-26 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


179 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Delta  Export  Lumber  Corporation — Continued. 

Delta  Hardwood  Lumber  Co.,  Rayville,  La 

Gayoso  Lumber  Co.,  Memphis,  Tenn 

Hackney,  R.  J.,  Lumber  Co.,  Memphis,  Tenn.. 

Holly  Ridge  Lumber  Co.,  Louisville,  Ky 

Howe  Lumber  Co.,  Helena,  Ark 

Howe  Neely  Lumber  Co.,  Helena,  Ark 

Hyde  Lumber  Co.,  South  Bend,  Ind 

Lamb  Gary  Lumber  Co.,  Vicksburg,  Miss 

May  Bros.,  Mem.phis,  Tenn 

Memphis  Band  Mill.  Co.,  Memphis,  Tenn 

Miller  Lumber  Co.,  Mariana,  Ark 

Mclntyre,  J.  F.,  &  Sons,  Pine  Bluff,  Ark 

Nickey  Bros.,  Memphis,  Tenn 

Norman,  E.  B.,  &  Co.,  Louisville,  Ky 

Paepcke  Leicht  Lumber  Co.,  Chicago,  111 

Penrod  Jurden  Co.,  Mem_phis,  Tenn 

Stark,  Jas.  E.,  &  Co.,  Memphis,  Tenn 

Stim.son,  J.  V.,  Hardwood  Co.,  Mem.phis,  Tenn. 

Stimson-  Veneer    &    Lumber    Co.,       Memphis, 

Tenn 


Douglas  Fir  Exploitation  &  Export  Co.,  San 
Francisco.  Name  changed  in  1937  to  Douglas 
Fir  Export  Co. ,  Seattle 

Formed  in  1918  to  sell  lumber  and  logs  (fir, 
hemlock,  cedar)  for  export  to  foreign  coun- 
tries; has  been  in  continuous  operation  to 
present  date.  The  association  reports  the 
following  advantages:  Economic  sales  cost 
through  centralized  office?  and  through 
agencies  and  correspondents  not  accessible 
to  individual  firms;  establishing  uniform 
sales  terms,  grades,  and  practices,  in  export 
trade;  obtaining  and  disseminating  foreign- 
trade  information  from  and  to  the  members; 
and  carrying  on  trade-promotion  work 
which  could  not  be  done  by  individual  firms 
owing  to  cost  involved. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Aberdeen  Lumber  &  Shingle  Co.,  Aberdeen, 
Wash 

Alexander,  F.  W.,  stock  trustee,  Seattle. 

American  Mill  Co.  (f;alled  Hulbert  Mill  Co.), 

Aberdeen,  Wash 

Ames,  E.  G.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Anacortes    Lumber    &    Box    Co.,    Anacortes, 

Wash 

Anderson  &  Middleton  Lumber  Co.,  Aber- 
deen ,  Wash 

Astoria  Box  &  Paper  Co.,  Astoria,  Greg 

Astoria  Box  Co.,  Astoria,  Ores 

Atlas  Lumber  &  Shingle  Co.,  Seattle 

Atlas  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle 

Baboock,  Thorpe,  Hoquiam,  Wash 

2577()il — 41  — No.  G i:i 


1922-26 

1922 

1922-26 

1922-24 

1922-26 

1922-26 

1922-25 

1923-26 

1922-26 

1922-26 

1922-26 

1922-26 

1922-26 

1923-26 

1922-25 

1922-26 

1922-26 

1922-26 

1922-26 


1918-21 
1919-39 

1922-26 
1918-26 

1931-37 

1918-27 
1931-35 
1920-21 
1921-22 
1921-24 
1926-29 


Period  of 
Total  num-     associ- 


ber  of 
members 


277 


ation 
opera- 
tion 


1918-39 


180 


oonCentration  of  economic  power 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT.  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2.074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Douglas  Fir  Exploitation  &  Export  Co. — Con. 

Baxter,  A.  A.,  Seattle 

Bay  City  Lumber  Co.,  Aberdeen,  Wash 

Bay  Park  Lumber  Co.,  North  Bend,  Greg 

Beaver  Linnton  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Oreg-- 

Beaver  Linnton  Mills,  Portland,  Greg 

Beaver  Lumber  Co.,  Prescott,  Greg 

Bishop,  E.  K.,  Lumber  Co.,  Aberdeen,  Wash. 

Bissell  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle,  Waih- 

Bloedel  Donovan  Lumber  Mills,  BeUingham, 

Bloedel.'j.  H.,  Seattle 

Bolcom-Caiial  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle 

Boner,  W.  H.,  Everett,  Wash 

Booth-Kelly  Lumber  Co.,   Eugene  and  Port- 
land, Greg 

Brace  &  Herget  Mill  Co.,  Seattle 

Bridal  Veil  Timber  Co.,  Bridal  Veil,  Greg 

Brighton   Mills   Co.,   Brighton  and  Portland, 

Greg 

Brix,  P.  J.,  Portland,  Greg 

Bryant  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle 

Buchanan  Lumber  Co.,  Glympia,  Wash 

Buehner  Lumber  Co.,  North  Beiid,  Greg 

Burhside,  R.  H.,  Raymond  and  Portland,  Oreg. 

Cahill,  A.  B,,  San  Francisco 

Campbell  Mill  Co..  Seattle 

Canyon  Lumber  Co.,  Everett,  Wash 

Carlisle  Lumber  Co.,  Onalaska,  Wash 

Carhsle  Pennell  Lumber  Co.,  Onalaska,  Wash  _ 

Carnation  Lumber  Co.,  Forest  Grove,  Greg 

Cascade  Lumber  &  Shingle  Co.,   Snohom.ish, 

Wash 

Cascade  Lumber  Co.,  Snohomish,  Wash 

Chambers,  J.  H.,  &  Son,  Cottage  Grove,  Greg.- 
Chehalis  Mill  Co. ,  Salkum,  Wash 

Chipman,  L.  L.,  Loiigview,  Wash 

Christenson,  E.  A.,  San  Francisco 

Clackamas  Fir  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Greg 

Clark  &  Wilson  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Greg 

Clark-Nickerson  Lumber  Co.,  Everett,  Wash__ 

Clark,  G.  M.,  Linnton,  Greg 

Clark,  W.  W.,  Portland,  Greg 

Clear  Fir  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Clear  Lake  Lumber  Co.,  Clear  Lake,  Wash 

Clough,  H.  J.,  Everett,  Wash 

Clough  Lumber  Co.,  Stanwood,  Wash 

Cobbs  &  Mitchell  Co.,  Portland,  Greg 

Columbia  Box  &  Lumber  Co.,  South  Bend, 
Wash 


1923-28 
1918-22 
1920-24 
1927-28 
1924-27 
191&-27 
1923-38 
1931-33 

1918-39 
1918-39 
1920-21 
1918-25 

1921-39 
1920-21 
1930-37 

1921-27 
1920-27 
1920-27 
1920-36 
1918-22 
1918-32 
1922-28 
1920-24 
1918-35 
1931-36 
1921-24 
1931-39 

1922-27 

1927-29 

1931-39 

1934-39 

/ 1925-27 

11931-32 

1918-22 

1934-39 

J1918-19 

11931-32 

1918-32 

1918-19 

1931-32 

1918-35 

1921-27 

1922-25 

/ 1922-23 

11927-33 

(1921-24 

11931-39 

/1919-22 
11925-28 


OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


181 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Period  of 

Total  num- 

associ- 

Years 

ber  of 

ation 

members 

opera- 
tion 

Douglas  Fir  Exploitation  &  Export  Co. — Con. 

Columbia   County   Lumber   Co.,    St.    Helens, 

Greg 

1919-23 

Columbia  River  Lumber  Co.,  Kalama,  Wash-_ 

1919-22 

Columbia  River  Paper  Mills,  Portland,  Oreg-.- 

1931-32 

Condon,  R.  W.,  Seattle,  Wash 

1927-28 

Connell,  Sam,  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Greg 

1919-21 

Cook,  A.  W.,  Jr.,  Portland,  Greg 

1930-31 

Cooney,  Xeil,  Cosm.opolis,  Wash 

1927-29 

Coos  Ba}^  Logging  Co.,  North  Bend,  Greg . 

1924-32 

Coos  Bav  Lumber  Co.,  Marshfield,  Greg 

1925-27 

Corvallis  Lumber  Co.,  CorvaUis,  Greg 

1930-39 

i 

Cram,  W.  S.,  Raymond,  Wash 

1922-28 

1 

Crossett  Western  Co.,  Wauna,  Greg 

1924-39 

1 

Crossett  Western  Lumber  Co.,  Wauna,  Greg-.. 

1918-24 

1 

Crown  Lumber  Co.,  Mukilteo,  Wash 

1918-38 

1 

Danaher  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

1918-22 

1 

Defiance  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash     

1918-39 
/ 1922-33 
11935-39 

Demarest,  E.  W.,  Tacoma,  Wash  .  .      

' 

Dempsev  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

1918-38 

DesChutes  River  Sawmills,  Glvmpia,  Wash 

1931-35 

' 

Dichter,  Theo.,  Warrentoii,  Greg 

1933-39 

1 

Dickman  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

1922-39 

1 

Dole,  W.  H.,  Hoquiam,  Wash 

1929-34 

Dolge,  Ernest,  Tacoma,  Wash 

/ 1922-23 
\1936-39 

' 

Dolge,  Ernest,  Inc.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

1919-39 

Dollar  Portland  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

1924-28 

Donovan,  J.  .J.,  Bellingham,  Wash 

1918-19 

Donovan  Lumber  Co.,  Aberdeen,  Wash 

1918-39 

Donovan  Lumber  Co.,  MiU  No.  2,  Aberdeen, 

1 

Wash 

1925-39 

1 

Donovan,  Wm.,  Aberdeen,  Wash 

1918-38 
1924-39 

1 

Doud,  L.  L.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

DuBois  Lumber  Co.,  Vancouver,  Wash 

1920-39 

DuBois,  W.  B.,  Vancouver,  Wash 

1923-39 

Duwamish  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

1921-25 

1 

Eagle  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Greg 

1921-39 

East  Side  Mill  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

1931-38 

East  Side  Mill  &  Timber  Co.,  Portland,  Greg 

1931-35 

Eatonville  Lumber  Co.,  Eatonville,  Wash 

1921-39 

Eclipse  Mill  Co.,  Everett,  Wash .    ..- 

1931-33 

Ellis  Mvlroie  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

1920-22 

1 

Eureka    Cedar    Lumber   &    Shingle'  Co.,    Ho- 

1 

quiam,  Wash 

1918-24 

Ferry  Baker  Lumber  Co.,  Everett,  Wash 

1918-26 

Fidalgo  Mill  &  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Greg 

1920-21 

Fir  Products  Co.,  Montesano,  Wash 

1920-22 

, 

Fir  Tree  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

1921-27 

Force.  L.  E.,  Seattle,  Wash 

1935-39 

i 

Gauge  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

1930-39 

Gerlinger,  Geo.  T.,  Portland,  Greg 

1922-39 

Grays   Harbor   Commercial   Co.,    Cosmopolis, 

Wash 

1918-30 

• 

182 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


1  Period  of 
Total  num-     associ- 

ber  of 
members 


Douglas  Fir  Exploitation  &  Export  Co. — Con. 

Grays  Harbor  Lumber  Co.,  Hoquiam,  Wash_- 

Gregory,  J.  T.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Griggs,  E.  G.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Gruber-Docherty  Lumber  Co.,Yelm,  Wash 

Guerrier,  J.  P.,  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Greg 

Guistina  Bros.,  Eugene,  Greg 

Hambidge,  R.,  Everett,  Wash 

Hammond,  A.  B.,  San  Francisco 

Hammond  Lumber  Co.,  Astoria,  Greg 

Hanify  Lumber  Co.,  Raymond,  Wash 

Hart-Wood  Lumber  Co.,  Raymond,  Wash 

Hauptman,  S.  M.,  San  Francisco 

Helms,  C.  E.,  San  Francisco 

Henry  Mill  &  Timber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Henry,  W.  Yale,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Hill,  Charles  E.,  Seattle 

Hoquiam    Lumber   &   Shingle    Co.,    Hoquiam, 

Wash 

Hulbert  Mill  Co.,  Aberdeen,  Wash 

Island  Lumber  Co.,  St.  Helens,  Greg 

Johnson,  E.  E.,  Lumber  Co.,  Coquille,  Greg 

Jones  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Greg 

Kalama  Lumber  &  Shingle  Co.,  Kalama,  Wash 

Kingsley,  E.  D.,  Linnton,  Greg 

Kingsley,  G.  Arch,  Linnton,  Greg 

Kingsley  Lumber  Co.,  Linnton,  Greg 

Kirk,  H.,  Portland,  Greg 

Kleeb  Lumber  Co.,  South  Bend,  Wash 

Knapp,  F.  C,  Portland,  Greg 

Knappton    Mills   &    Lumber   Co.,    Knappton, 

Wash 

Kreienbaum,  C.  H.,  Shelton,  Wash 

Lewis,  Charles  L.,  Raymond,  Wash . 

Lewis  Lumber  Co.,  Pengra  and  Dexter,  Greg-  - 
Lewis  Mill.s  &  Timber  Co  ,  South  Bend,  Wash_- 

Long  Bell  Lumber  Co.,  Longview,  Wash 

Long  Bell   Lumber  Sales  Corporation,   Long- 
view,  Wash 

Manlcy  Moore  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash__ 

Marine  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

McCleary,    Henry,    Timber    Co.,     McCleary, 

Wash _■ 

McCormick,  Chas.  R.,  Lumber  Co.,  San  Fran- 
cisco  

McCready,  Fred  H.,  Aberdeen,  Wash 

McKenna  Lumber  Co.,  McKenna,  Wash 

Mickle  Mills,  Portland,  Greg 

Middleton,  A.  W.,  Aberdeen,  Wash 

Mineral  Lake  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Moore  Mill  &  Lumber  Co.,  Bandon,  Greg 

Morris,  J.  E.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Morrison  Mill  Co.,  Anacortes,  Wash 


1919-22 
1921-22 
1918-38 
1931-39 
1924-31 
1931-39 
1927-28 
1919-24 
1919-24 
1918-27 
1924-32 
1918-33 
1933-35 
1923-39 
1920-25 
1918-20 

1918-29 
1918-22 
1919-26 
1925-28 
1921-26 
1918-19 
1922-38 
1938-39 
1937-39 
1918-23 
1919-21 
1922-28 

1918-32 
1933-39 
1918-22 
1930-31 
1935-39 
1924-31 
1925-27 

1931-32 
1921-33 
1920-22 

1931-39 

1926-38 
1933-35 
1938-39 
1921-32 
1924-26 
1918-27 
1921-23 
1931-39 
1933-34 
1920-21 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


183 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Total  num 

ber  of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Douglas  Fir  Exploitation  &  Export  Co. — Con. 

Mountain  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Multnomah  Lumber  &  Box  Co.,  Portland,  Oreg_ 
Mumby  Lumber  &  Shingle  Co.,  Bordeaux  and 

Mumby,  Wash 

Mutual  Lumber  Co.,  Bucoda,  Wash 

National  Lumber  &  Manufacturing  Co.,  Ho- 

quiam,  Wash 

Nelson,  Chas.,  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Nettleton  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle 

Nettleton,  W.  B.,  Seattle 

Ninemire  Lumber  Co.,  Port  Angeles,  Wash 

North  Bend  Mills  &  Lumber  Co.,  North  Bend, 

Greg 

North  End  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

North  Western  Lumber  Co.,  Hoquiam,  Wash 

Olympia  Harbor  Lumber  Co.,  Olympia,  Wash.. 
Olympic  Forest  Products  Co.,   Port  Angeles, 

Wash - 

Oregon-American  Lumber  Corporation,  Port- 
land, Oreg 

Oregon  Box  &  Manufacturing  Co.,  Portland, 

Oregon  Lumber  Co.,  Dee,  Oreg 

Oregon  Ship  Timber  Mills,  Portland,  Oreg 

Oregon  Timber  Mills,  Linnton,  Oreg 

Ostrander  Ry.  &  Timber  Co.,  Ostrander,  Wash. 

Pacific  Box  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Pacific  National  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash.. 

Pacific  Spruce  Corporation,  Portland,  Oreg 

Pacific  States  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Page  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Paine,  A.  L.,  Hoquiam,  Wash 

P.  &  G.  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Parker  Lumber  <fe  Box  Co.,  Everett,  Wash 

Parker-Poyneer  Lumber  Co.,  Everett,  Wash 

Peabody,  W.  H.,  Everett,  Wash 

Peninsula  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Oreg 

Penn  Lumber  Co.,  McGlynn,  Oreg 

Peterman  Manufacturing  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash.. 

Pope  &  Talbot  Lumber  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Port  Blakely  Mill  Co.,  Port  Blakely,  Wash 

Portland  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Oreg 

Prouty  Lumber  &  Box  Co.,  Warrenton,  Greg.. 

Puget  Mill  Co.,  Port  Gamble,  Wash 

Puget  Sound  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Puget    Sound    Lumber    Manufacturing    Co., 

Renton,  Wash 

Puget  Sound  Mills  &  Timber  Co.,  Port  Angeles, 

Wash -- 

Puget  Sound  Pulp  &  Timber  Co.,  Clear  Lake, 

Wash 

Puget  Sound  Sawmills  &  Shingle  Co.,  Belling- 

ham,  Wash 

Quinault  Lumber  Co.,  Raymond,  Wash 

Raymond  Lumber  Co.,  Raymond,  Wash 


1925-39 
1931-33 

1921-39 
1931-32 

1918-26 
1925-38 
1921-39 
1924-39 
1925-26 

1918-22 
1920-38 
1918-34 
1931-39 

1931-37 

1925-39 
1920-21 
1933-39 
1920-21 
1921-23 
1931-39 
1919-21 
1921-39 
1925-29 
1921-39 
1921-23 
1918-26 
1920-22 
1925-27 
1927-31 
1927-33 
1918-28 
1931-37 
1931-33 
1938-39 
1918-24 
1918-24 
1931-39 
1918-26 
1918-31 

1931-37 

1918-25 

1931-32 

1919-30 
1918-27 
1918-31 


184 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Douglas  Fir  Exploitation  &  Export  Co. — Con. 

Raymond  Veneer  Co.,  Raymond,  Wash 

Rayonier,  Inc.,  Port  Angeles,  Wash 

Reed,  Mark,  Shelton,  Wash 

Reed  Mill  Co.,  Shelton,  Wash 

Ribenack,  W.  C,  San  Francisco 

Robinson  Manufacturing  Co.,  Everett,  Wash.. 

Ryan,  J.  A.,  Portland,  Oreg 

St.  Helens  Lumber  Co.,  St.  Helens,  Oree 

St.  Helens  Tie  &  Timber  Co.,  St.  HelenSj^^Oreg.. 
St.  Paul  &  Tacoma  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash. 

Sammamish  Lumber  Co.,  Issaquah,  Wash 

Schwager  Nettleton  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle 

Seattle  Mill  &  Logging  Co.,  Seattle 

Shaffer  Box  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Sharp,  R.  J.,  Tacoma,  Waslx 

Ship  Lumber  Mill  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Siler  Mill  Co.,  Raymond,  Wash 

Silver  Falls  Timber  Co.,  Silverton,  Oreg 

Silverton  Lumber  Co.,  Silverton,  Oreg 

Simpson  Logging  Co.,  Shelton,  Wash 


Skookum  Lumber  Co.,  Tenino,  Wash 

Snellstrom  Bros.,  Inc.,  Vaughan,  Oreg 

Snellstrom  Lumber  Co.,  Eugene,  Oreg 

Snoqualmie    Falls    Lumber    Co.,    Snoqualmie 

Falls    Wash __ 
South  Bend  MUls  &  T[mber"Co","South'Bend, 

WTash 

South  SeattleMilf  Co.,  Seattle 

South  Side  Lumber  Co.,  Montesano,  Wash 

Southeast  Portland  Lumber  Co.,  Lents,  Oreg-. 
Spaulding,  Chas.  K.,  Logging  Co.,  Portland, 

Oreg 

Springer  Mill  Co.,  Olympia,  Wash 

Standard    Box    &    Lumber   Co.,    Buxton   and 

Portland,  Oreg 

Stimson  Mill  Co.,  Ballard,  and  Seattle,  Wash.. 

Stimson  Timber  Co.,  Seattle 


Stone,  E.  C,  Seattle 

Stout  Lumber  Co.,  North  Bend,  Oreg 

Tacoma  Harbor  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash. 

Tacoma  Mill  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Talbot,  F.  C,  San  Francisco 

Talbot,  W.  H.,  San  Francisco 

Thane,  A.  F.,  San  Francisco 

Thayer,  C.  A.,  San  Francisco 

ThorapsoiJ,  J.  W.,  Port  Gamble,  Wash 

Tidewater  Mill  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Titcomb,  F.  R.,  San  Francisco 


Tumwater  Lumber  Mills  Co.,  Olympia,  Wash. 
Turner  Creek  Lumber  Co.,  Yamhill,  Oreg 


1920-21 
1937-39 
1931-33 
1931-36 
1924-28 
1931-32 
1925-27 
1918-26 
1922-23 
1918-39 
1937-38 
1918-20 
1920-31 
1931-34 
1933-36 
1921-31 
1918-28 
1920-39 
1921-25 
1936-39 
1921-22 
1924-27 
1931-38 
1938-39 

1921-34 

1918-21 
1924-25 
1921-23 
1931-39 

1921-39 
1931-39 

1921-28 

1918 

1931-39 

1921-26 

1931-32 

1938-39 

1924-29 

1924-39 

1920-23 

1935-36 

1918-26 

1924-25 

1918-24 

1928-31 

1918-29 

1926-27 

1931-33 

1931-39 

1934-38 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


185 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FOKMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Douglas  Fir  Exploitation  &  Export  Co. — Con. 

Tyson,  James,  San  Francisco 

Van  Vleet  Lumber  Co.,  Rainier,  Greg 

Vincent,  H.  F.,  San  Francisco 

Wagner,  Corydon,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Walton,  Clyde,  Everett,  Wash 

Walton  Lumber  Co.,  Everett,  Wash 

Warrenton  Lumber  Co.,  Warrenton,  Greg 

Washington  Veneer«Co.,  Glympia,  Wash 

Watzek,  C.  H.,  Wauna,  Greg 

Wentworth,  Geo.  K.,  Jr.,  Portland,  Greg 

Wentworth,  L.  J.,  Portland,  Greg 

West,  A.  J.,  Lumber  Co.,  Aberdeen,  Wash 

West  Oregon  Lumber  Co.,  Linnton  and  Port- 
land, Greg 

West  Waterway  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle 

Western  Fir  Lumber  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Western  Lumber  Co.,  Aberdeen,   Wash.,  and 

Westfir,  Greg 

Western     Mill    Co.    of    Aberdeen,    Aberdeen, 

Wash 

Westport  Lumber  Co.,  Westport,  Greg 

Westwood  Lumber  Co.,  Wheeler,  Greg 

Weyerhaeuser  Timber   Co.,  Everett  and   Ta- 
coma, Wash 

Wheeler,  Chas.  L.,  San  Francisco 

Wheeler,  C.  H.,  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Greg.-. 

Whitman,  W.  A.,  Seattle 

Whitney  Co.,  The,  Tillamook  and   Garibaldi, 

Greg 

Wight,  E.  B.,  Everett,  Wash 

Willamette   River   Lumber   Co.,  Oregon  City 

and  Portland,  Greg 

Willamette   Valley    Lumber    Co.,    Dallas    and 

Portland,  Greg 

Willapa    Harbor    Lumber    Mills,    Raymond, 

Wash 

Willapa  Lumber  Co.,  Raymond,  Wash 

Wilson  Bros.  &  Co.,  Aberdeen,  Wash 

Wilson,  J.  H.,  Aberdeen,  Wash 

Wood  &  Iverson,  Inc.,  Hobart,  Wash 

Wood,  E.  K.,  Lumber  Co.,  Aberdeen,  Belling- 

ham,  Hoquiam,  and  Anacortes,  Wash 

Woodard,  M.  C,  Westport  and  Portland,  Greg.. 
Woodard,  W.  A.,  Lumber  Co.,  Cottage  Grove, 

Greg 

ii'oemans  Lumber  Co..  Pe  Ell,  Wash 


Durex  Abrasives  Corporation,  New  York 

Organized  in  1929  by  some  of  the  companies 
formerly  exporting  through  the  American 
Surface  Abrasives  Export  Corporation,  the 
association  sells  its  members'  products  in 
foreign  countries.  It  reports  that  "Ability 
to  represent  the  members  in  foreign  markets 
through  shipments  to  distributors  and  con- 


1918-38 

1938-39 

1924-39 

1938-39 

1932-39 

1919-39 

1920-25 

1931-39 

1928-39 

1918-22 

1918 

1918-28 

1918-39 
1920-39 
1921-35 

1918-37 

1922-23 
1918-39 
1925-28 

1918-34 
1936-39 
1921-23 
1928-39 

1920-27 
1925-27 

1921-24 

1921-39 

1931-32 
1918-31 
1918-39 
1929-39 
1921-26 

1919-39 
1918-39 

1931-39 
1921-26 


1929-39 


186 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Durex  Abrasives  Corporation — Continued. 

sumers  in  those  markets,  with  the  corollary 
function  of  central  credit  control,  agreement 
upon  price  for  export,  plus  economies  of  op- 
eration obtained  through  group  shipments, 
give  us  advantages  not  possessed  by  indi- 
vidual exporters." 

Members  (stockholders) 

American  Glue  Co.,  Boston 

Armour  &  Co.,  Chicago 

Baeder  Adamson  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Barton,  H.  H.,  &  Son,  Philadelphia 

Behr-Manning  Corporation,  Troy,  N.  Y 

Carborundum  Co.,  The,  Niagara  Falls,  N.  Y.. 
Minnesota  Mining  &   Ma;  afacturing  Co.,  St. 

Paul,  Minn 

U.  S.  Sandpaper  Co.,  Will  amsport,  Pa 

Wausau  Abrasives  Co.,  Wausau,  Wis 


Electrical  Apparatus  Export  Association,  New  York. 
Organized  in  1931,  for  exportation  of  electrical 
and  other  apparatus  and  materials  to  foreign 
markets. 

Members 

Allis  Chalmers  Manufacturing  Co.,  Milwaukee 

Allis,  Louis,  Co.,  The 

Anaconda  Wire  &  Cable  Co.,  New  York 

Canadian  Porcelain  Co.,  Hamilton,  Canada 

Duncan  Electric  Manufacturing  Co.,  Lafayette, 

Ind 

Electric  Furnace  Co.,  Salem,  Ohio 

Electric  Service  Supply  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Elliott  Co.,  New  York 

Fretz-Moon  Tube  Co.,  Butler,  Pa 

General  Motors  Corporation,  Export  Division, 

New  York 

Goodman  Manufacturing  Co.,  Chicago 

International  General  Electric  Co.,  New  York.. 

Jeffrey  Manufacturing  Co.,  Columbus,  Ohio 

Kelvinator,  Detroit 

Line  Material  Co.,  South  Milwaukee 

Nash  Kelvinator  Corporation,  Detroit 

National  Electric  Products  Corporation,  Pitts- 
burgh  

Norge    Division,    Borg-Warner    Corporation, 

Detroit 

Ohio  Brass  Co.,  New  York 

Okonite  Co.,  The,  Passaic,  N.  J 

Phelps   Dodge   Copper  Pioducts  Corporation, 

New  York 

Reliance    Electric    &    Engineering    Co.,    New 

York 

Sangamo  Electric  Co.,  Springfield,  111 


192&-31 
1929-39 
1929-31 
1929-31 
1929-39 
1929-39 

1929-39 
1929-31 
1929 


1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1934-39 

1936-39 
1937-39 
1936-39 
1938-39 
1939 

1938-39 
1934-39 
1931-39 
1934-39 
1938-39 
1936-39 
1939 

1939 

193&-39 
1934-39 
1937-39 

1937-39 

1938-39 
1936-39 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


28 


1931-39 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


187 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Electrical  Apparatus  Export  Association — Con. 
Sperrv  Gyroscope  Co.,  Inc.,  Brooklyn,  N.  Y. 

U.  S. "Rubber  Export  Co.,  Ltd.,  New  York 

Walker  Bros.,  New  York 

Westinghouse    Electric    &    International  Co., 

New  York 

Youngstown  Sheet  &  Tube  Co.,  New  York 

Electrical  Export  Corporation,   Wilmington,   DeL. 
Organized  in  January  1940,  to  ship  electrical 
apparatus    and   materials    to    foreign    coun- 
tries. 

Members  (stockholders) 

International  General  Electric  Co.,  Inc.,  N.  Y.. 
Westinghouse  Electric  International  Co.,  N.  Y_. 

Export  Clothes  Pin  Association  of  America,  Inc., 
New  York 

Organized  in  1919  to  ship  wooden  clothespins 
to  foreign  markets,  the  association  operated 
successfully  for  several  years.  It  reported 
as  an  outstanding  advantage,  ability  of  the 
members,  through  association  action,  to 
"present  a  solid  front  to  foreign  competi- 
tion *  *  *  acting  independently  the 
factories  would  be  competing  against  each 
other  and  thus  dissipating  their  strength." 
In  1929  their  exports  were  considerably  less 
due  to  foreign  competition — German  and 
Swedish  producers  undersold  the  American 
group  from  5  to  10  percent.  Members 
Mere  unwilling  to  sell  at  the  lower  prices, 
and  association  exports  were  abandoned  in 
1930. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Ber.st,  Forster,  Dixfield  Co.,  Dixfield,  Maine 

Cane,  Wm.,  &  Sons  Co.,  Ltd.,  Newmarket, 
Ontario 

Clarke  Bros.,  Ltd.,  Bear  River,  Nova  Scotia 

Escanaba  Manufacturing  Co.,  Escanaba,  Mich. 
Fulton  Manufacturing  Co.,  Richwood,  W.Va-- 
Indiana    Wood    Products    Co.,     Martinsville, 

Ind 

Northern     Woodenware     Co.,     Island     Falls, 

Maine 

Oval  Wood  Dish  Co.,  Tupper  Lake,  N.  Y 

Richmond  Cedar  Works,  Richmond,  Va 

Steele- Wallace  Corporation,  Richwood,  W.  Va- 
Summit  Lumber  Co.,  Davidson,  Maine 


Export  Petroleum  Association,  Inc.,  New  York 

Formed  in  1929  for  exportation  of  petroleum 
and  petroleum  products,  the  association  in- 
cluded the  Standard  Oil  Export  Corporation 
(also  filing  papers  under  the  act)  and  other 


Years 


1939 

1937-39 

1939 

1931-39 
1939 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1940 


11  1919-30 


1920-30 

1919-30 
1920-21 
1919-23 
1919-24 

1919-30 

1919-30 
1919-30 
1919-30 
1924-30 
1919-30 


17  1929-36 


188 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Export  Petroleum  Association,  Inc. — Continued. 

companies.  Substantial  business  was  trans- 
acted prior  to  1931,  when  conditions  in  for- 
eign markets  led  to  suspension  of  the  asso- 
ciation agreements;  thereafter  members  sold 
individually.  The  association  continued  to 
file  reports  until  formal  dissolution  in  1936. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Atlantic  Refining  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Cities  Service  Co.,  New  York 

Continental  Oil  Co.,  Ponca  City,  Okla 

Gulf  Refining  Co.,  Pittsburgh 

Marland  Oil  Co.,  Ponca  City,  Okla 

Pure  Oil  Co.,  Chicago 

Richfield  Oil  Co.  of  California,  Los  Angeles 

Shell-Union  Oil  Corporation,  New  York 

Sinclair  Consolidated  Oil  Co.,  New  York 

Standard  Oil  Co.  of  California,  San  Francisco 

Standard  Oil  Co.  (Indiana),  Chicago 

Standard  Oil  Co.  of  New  York,  New  York 

Standard  Oil  Export  Corporation,  New  York 

Texas  Corporation,  The,  New  York 

Tidewater- Associated  Oil  Co.,  New  York 

Union  Oil  Co.  of  California,  Los  Angeles 

Vacuum  Oil  Co.,  New  York 


Export  Screw  Association   of  the   United  States, 
Providence,  R.I 

The  association  was  formed  in  1926  for  exporta- 
tion of  screws  to  foreign  countries.  During 
the  past  few  years,  its  activities  have  been 
restricted  by  depressed  conditions  abroad, 
and  by  keen  competition  of  continental  and 
Japanese  manufacturers;  but  the  association 
is  still  filing  papers  under  the  act. 

Members 

American  Hardware  Corporation,  New  Britain, 

Conn 

American  Screw  Co.,  Providence,  R.  I 

Bridgeport  Screw  Co.,  Bridgeport,  Conn 

Continental  Wood  Screw  Co.,   New  Bedford, 

Mass.- 

Corbin  Screw  Corporation,  The,  New  Britain, 

Conn 

Eagle  Lock  Co.,  New  York 

Parker,  Charles,  Co.,  The,  New  York 

Reed  &  Prince  Manufacturing  Co.,  Worcester, 

Mass 


Exporters  of  Wood  Products,  Inc.,  New  York 

Organized  in  1924  to  ship  barrel  staves  used 
for  wine  casks  in  Argentina,  the  association 
operated  successfully  in  years  when  the  grape 


Years 


1929-36 
1929-36 
1930-32 
1929-36 
1929-30 
1929-36 
1929-36 
1929-36 
1929-36 
1929-36 
1929-32 
1929-36 
1929-36 
1929-36 
1929-36 
1929-36 
1929-36 


1926-27 
1926-39 
1926-39 

1930-39 

1927--39 
1926-39 
1926-39 

1930-39 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


189 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Exporters  of  Wood  Products,  Inc. — Continued. 

crop  in  that  country  was  good.  In  1929  the 
members  voted  to  dissolve,  but  several  of 
them  were  still  interested  in  export  trade  and 
therefore  formed  the  Shook  Exporters  Asso- 
ciation, which  has  been  in  operation  since 
1932  (see  Shook  Exporters  Association.) 

Members  (stockholders) 

Chickasaw    Wood    Products    Co.,    Memphis, 
Tenn 

Export  Cooperage  Co.,  Memphis,  Tenn 

Gulf  Cooperage  Co . ,  Pittsburgh 

Hamlen,  J.  H.,  &  Son,  Portland,  Maine 

Moore,  Lucas  E.,  Stave  Co.,  New  York 

Paducah  Cooperage  Co.,  Paducah,  Ky 

Pekin  Cooperage  Co.,  New  York__.^ 


Exporting  Rye   MiUers  Association,    Minneapolis, 

Minn 

Formed  in  1920  for  the  primary  purpose  of 
selling  rye  flour  and  meal  to  the  Norwegian 
Government  Food  Commission,  the  associ- 
ation became  dissolved  when  the  Norwegian 
Government  discontinued  its  purchases. 

Members 


Blodgett-Holmes  Co.,  Janesville,  Wis 

Eckhart  Milling  Co.,  Chicago 

Kern,  J.  B.  A.,  &  Sons,  Inc.,  Milwaukee. 
PiUsbury  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Minneapolis... 
Shane  Bros.  &  Wilson  Co.,  Minneapolis.. 

Stern,  Bernhard,  &  Sons,  Milwaukee 

Stratton-Ladish  Milling  Co.,  Milwaukee . 
Voight  Milling  Co.,  Grand  Rapids,  Mich. 
Washburn-Crosby  Co.,  Minneapolis 


Florida  Hard  Rock  Phosphate  Export  Association, 

Savannah,  Ga • 

In  operation  since  1919,  exporting  phosphate 
hard  rock  to  foreign  countries.  Members  are 
in  Florida  and  Georgia;  the  rock  is  therefore 
shipped  to  Fernandina,  washed,  crushed, 
and  stored  in  warehouses  at  the  port,  from 
which  it  is  loaded  on  steamers  for  foreign 
shipment.  (The  association  has  at  times 
cooperated  with  the  Florida  Pebble  Phos- 
phate Export  Association,  and  with  the 
Phosphate  Export  Association,  which  ships 
pebble  phosphate  rock.)  It  reports  that 
"Operating  as  an  association  is  essential  to 
reap  greatest  benefits  in  the  export  market." 


Years 


1924-29 
1924-29 
1924-29 
1924-29 
1924-26 
1925-29 
1924-29 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Periodcrf 
assocl-^ 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1920 


1919-39 


190 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Florida  Hard  Rock  Phosphate  Export  Association  — 
Continued. 

Members 

Buttgenbach  &  Co.,  Dunnellon,  Fla.,  and  Lake- 
land, Fla 

Camp,  C.  &  J.,  Ocala,  Fla 

Cummer  Lumber  Co.,  Jacksonville,  Fla 

Dunnellon  Phosphate  Co.,  Savannah,  Ga 

Dunnellon  Phosphate  Mining 'Co.,  Savannah, 

Ga 

Mutual  Mining  Co.,  Savannah,  Ga 

Norfleet,  P.  J.  &  J.  H.,  Newberrv,  Fla 

Thompson,  T.  A.,  Fort  White,  Fla 

Florida  Pebble  Phosphate  Export  Association,  New 
York 

Formed  in  1919  to  export  pebble  phosphate 
rock,  the  association  had  some  of  the  same 
members  as  the  Phosphate  Export  Associa- 
tion, organized  in  the  same  j'car,  to  ship  the 
same  product.  The  two  groups  used  the 
same  office  and  had  some  of  the  same  officers. 
In  1933  the  Ore  &  Chemical  Co.,  a  member 
of  Phosphate  Export  Association,  resigned, 
leaving  the  membership  of  that  group  iden- 
tical with  that  of  the  Florida  Pebble  group. 
It  was  therefore  decided  to  consolidate  the 
two  under  the  name  of  the  Phosphate  Ex- 
port Association,  which  is  still  in  successful 
operation.  Cooperative  agreements  have 
been  entered  into  by  these  groups  with  the 
Florida  Hard  Rock  Phosphate  Export  As- 
sociation, also  operating  under  the  act.  The 
association  reported  that  "the  exploitation 
of  foreign  markets  can  be  better  handled  by 
a  large,  single,  and  well-working  organization 
than  by  a  number  of  smaller  organizations 
all  working  against  each  other.  Concentra- 
tion of  effort,  standardization  of  grades, 
lower  selling  costs,  are  a  benefit  not  only  to 
the  American  exporter  but  also  to  the  for- 
eign consumer,  and  are  important  factors  in 
the  endeavor  to  increase  export  sales." 

Members 

American    Agricultural    Chemical    Co.,    Nev. 

York 

American  Cyanamid  Co.,  New  York 

Coronet  Phosphate  Co.,  New  York 

International   Agricultural   Corporation,    New 

York 


1920-22 
1933-39 
1919-27 
1933-39 
1919-27 
1919-28 

1927-39 
1919-33 
1921 
1921-27 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1919-33 
1919-33 
1922-26 

1919-33 


1919-33 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


191 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  o 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Florida  Pebble  PhoBphate  Export  Association — Con. 
Morris  Fertilizer  Co.,  Chicago  (branch,  Armour 

Fertilizer  Works) 

Phosphate  Mining  Co.,  New  York 

Southern  Phosphate  Corporation,  Baltimore 

Florida  Pine  Export  Association,  Jacksonville,  Fla_. 
Organized  in  1930  to  export  yellow  pine  lumber 
and  timber  to  South  America,  through  the 
Pensacola  Lumber  &  Timber  Co.  (one  of  the 
member  companies)  as  sales  manager,  the 
association  reported  in  1931  that  it  had  been 
unable  to  operate  due  to  the  "general  depres- 
sion in  the  export  lumber  market";  it  was 
therefore  dissolved.  (Two  of  the  member 
companies,  the  Pensacola  Lumber  &  Timber 
Co.  and  the  St.  Andrews  Bay  Lumber  Co., 
were  members  of  the  Alabama-Florida  Pitch 
Pine  Export  Association,  which  operated 
under  the  act  from  1929  to  1933.) 

Members 

Foshee  Manufacturing  Co.,  Melbourne,  Fla 

Griffin,  J.  M.,  Lumber  Co.,  Holopaw,  Fla 

Pensacola  Lumber  &  Timber  Co,,  Pensacola,  Fla. 

Putnam  Lumber  Co.,  Shamrock,  Fla 

Sherman,  W.  C,  Co.,  Hicoria,  Fla 

St.  Andrews  Bay  Lumber  Co.,  Millville,  Fla 

Foundry    Equipment   Export   Corporation,   Phila- 
delphia  

Organized  in  November  1919,  to  export  foundry 
equipment  and  allied  products;  some  pre- 
liminary work  was  done;  a  representative 
made  a  survej'  of  foreign  markets  in  1920, 
but  the  plans  did  not  materialize  and  the 
members  agreed  to  dissolve  the  corporation 
early  in  1921. 

Members   (stockholders) 

American  Foundry  Equipment  Co.,  New  York- . 
American  Molding  Machine  Co.,  Terre  Haute, 
Ind 

Arcade  Manufacturing  Co.,  Freeport,  111 

Buch  Foundry  Equipment  Co.,  York,  Pa 

Grimes  Molding  Machine  Co.,  Detroit 

National  Engineering  Works,  Chicago 

Obermayer,  S.  Co.,  The,  Chicago 

Paxson,  J.  W.,  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Whiting  Foundry  Equipment  Co.,  Harvey,  111.. 

Woodison,  E.  J.,  Co.,  Detroit 

Wonham,  Bates  &  Goode,  New  York 


1922-24 
1919-26 
1930-33 


1930-31 


11 


1919-21 


192 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS'  FOKMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


(jieneral  Alcohol  Export  Corporation,  New  York 

Organized  in  1919  to  ship  spirits  and  alcohol, 
the  company  did  substantial  business  until 
the  prohibition  amendment  was  passed. 
There  were  then  compHcations  since  regula- 
tions required  assurance  from  the  foreign 
buyer  that  the  alcohol  shipped  would  not  be 
used  for  beverages  purposes;  and  there  were 
long  delays  in  obtaining  export  permits,  re- 
sulting in  cancelations  by  foreign  buyers. 
The  corporation  was  finally  dissolved  in 
1924.  The  principal  advantage  reported 
was  "the  opportunity  and  ability  to  execute 
larger  orders  or  a  larger  volume  of  orders 
than  could  be  done  individually.  The  asso- 
ciation had  the  combined  facilities  of  many 
individual  operating  plants,  and  by  aggre- 
gating orders  and  apportioning  same  accord- 
ing to  relative  individual  capacity,  ship- 
ments were  expedited  and  efficiency  was 
promoted." 

Members  (stockholders) 


Bacharach,  Charles,  New  Orleans. 

Delany,  Frank  J.,  Chicago 

Harrison,  Frederic  M.,  New  York. 

K^ssler,  Julius,  New  York 

Publicker,  Harry,  Philadelphia 

Publicker,  Philip,  Philadelphia 

WUson,  Everett  W.,  Pekin,  111 

Wolfner,  Wm.  F.,  Peoria,  111 


Years 


General  Milk  Company,  Inc.,  New  York 

Organized  in  1919  as  American  Milk  Products 
Corporation  (name  changed  in  1931)  the 
company  was  very  successful  in  developing 
exports  of  canned  milk,  reheving  the  do- 
mestic market  of  surplus  production  (as  a 
result  of  expansion  to  meet  war  needs)  and 
supplying  a  substantial  demand  in  Europe. 
In  later  years,  the  canned  milk  industry 
abroad  has  expanded,  in  line  with  efforts 
toward  becoming  self-sustaining  in  food- 
stuffs, and  exports  to  that  market  have 
lessened.  Some  members  of  the  export  com- 
pany met  this  situation  by  establishing 
branch  factories  abroad;  and  sales  of  the  ex- 
port company  have  now  been  shifted  to 
tropical  countries  where  there  is  no  domestic 
production.  It  is  reported  that  "the  out- 
standing advantage  obtained  by  this  cor- 
poration operating  under  the  Webb-Pomer- 
ene  Act  is  the  large  source  of  supplies  avail- 
able from  the  member  companies;  and  these 
sources  extending  as  they  do  to  all  of  the 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


1919-24 
1919-24 
1919-24 
1919-24 
1919-24 
1919-24 
1919-24 
1919-24 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1919-24 


I 

39 

J 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


193 


120  ASSOCIATIONS'  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


General  Milk  Company,  Inc.-^Continued. 

principal  dairying  States  of  tbe  United  States, 
enable  our  corporation  to  have  the  goods 
shipped  to  the  most  convenient  ports  nearest 
the  foreign  country  to  which  they  are  to  be 
exported,  and  to  secure  the  lowest  inland 
freight  rates  from  factories  to  ports," 

Members  (stockholders) 

Carnation  Milk  Products  Co.,  Chicago,  Ocon- 

omowoc.  Wis.,  and  Milwaukee 

Helvetia  Milk  Condensing  Co.,  Highland,  111.. 
Highland  Milk  Condensing  Co.,  Elkland,  Pa... 
Pet  Milk  Co.,  St.  Louis 


Goodyear  Tire  &  Rubber  Export  Co.,  Akron,  Ohio.. 
The  company  exports  rubber  products  (tires, 
tubes,  belting,  hose,  etc.)  purchased  from 
the  Goodyear  Tire  &  Rubber  Co.,  which 
owns  all  stock  of  the  export  company.  It 
also  cooperates  with  other  rubber  exporters 
as  a  member  of  the  Rubber  Export  Associa- 
tion, another  group  operating  under  the  act. 

Grain  Products  Export  Association,  New  York _. 

Formed  in  1922  by  the  American  Corn  Prod- 
ucts Export  Association  (also  filing  as  an 
export  group  under  the  act)  and  the  Corn 
Products  Refining  Co.,  to  ship  corn  sirup, 
corn  sugar  and  cornstarch,  a  substantial 
business  was  developed,  successfully  dis- 
posing of  the  surplus  production  built  up 
during  the  war.  It  was  reported  that  "the 
facilities  allowed  us  under  the  Webb-Pome- 
rene  Act  place  us  in  a -position  to  combat 
foreign  competition  in  a  way  that  woujd  not 
otherwise  be  possible."  After  several  years, 
however,  exports  were  affected  by  increased 
production  abroad  and  tariff  barriers,  and 
the  association  became  dissolved  in  1927. 

Members 

American  Corn  Products  Export  Association, 
N.  Y 

Corn  Products  Refining  Co.,  N.  Y 


Grand  Rapids  Furniture  Export  Association,  Grand 
Rapids,  Mich 

Organized  in  1920  to  ship  furniture  and  to  pro- 
tect the  name  "Grand  Rapids  Furniture"  in 
foreign  markets,  the  association  did  some 
preliminary  work,  obtaining  trade  statistics 
and  foreign  market  information,  but  after  an 
investigation  of  foreign  freights  and  ex- 
change,  the  members  decided  that  export 


191^39 
191^23 
1919-20 
1923-39 


1922-39 


1922-2 


1922-27 
1922-27 


)'c 


1920-27 


194 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


J20  ASSOCIATIONS'  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEI^IBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Grand    Rapids    Furniture    Export    Association — 
Continued. 

business  in  so  bulky  and  so  expensive  a 
product  as  cabinet  furniture  was  impossible. 
They  therefore  became  dissolved  in  1927. 

Members 

Berkey  &  Gay  Furniture  Co.,  Grand  Rapids... 

Century  Furniture  Co.,  Grand  Rapids 

Criswell  Furniture  Co.,  Grand  Rapids 

Furniture  Studios,  Inc.,  Grand  Rapids 

Grand  Rapids  Chair  Co.,  Grand  Rapids 

Grand  Rapids  Refrigerator  Co.,  Grand  Rapids. 

Imperial  Furniture  Co.,  Grand  Rapids 

Luce  Furniture  Co.,  The,  Grand  Rapids 

Michigan  Chair  Co.,  Grand  Rapids 

Stickley  Bros.  Co.,  Grand  Rapids 

Widdicombe  Furniture  Co.,  The,  Grand  Rapids. 
Widdicombe,  John  C,  Grand  Rapids 


Grapefruit  Distributors,  Inc.,  Davenport,  Fla 

Organized  in  1930  to  export  fresh  and  canned 
citrus  fruits,  especially  grapefruit,  for  ac- 
count of  growers  and  shippers,  the  company 
was  handicapped  by  high  tariffs  abroad  and 
became  dissolved  in  1939. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Bates,  F.  S.,  Davenport,  Fla 

Dewson,  E.  H.,  Davenport,  Fla 

DiCristina,  Harry  E.,  Davenport,  Fla 

Gulf  Pitch  Pine  Export  Association,  New  Orleans, 
La 


Organized  in  1920  to  represent  the  member 
companies  in  sales  of  yellow  pitch  pine  lum- 
ber and  timber,  in  foreign  markets,  operated 
successfully  for  several  years  using  the 
oflBces  of  the  Standard  Export  Lumber  Co. 
of  New  Orleans,  and  doing  substantial 
business  (chiefly  with  Latin-American  coun- 
tries). This  association  had  cooperative 
agreements  with  the  Alabama-Florida  Pitch 
Pine  Export  Association,  .  also  operating 
under  the  act.  Beginning  about  1931,  busi- 
ness was  affected  by  revolutions  and  political 
unrest  in  South  America,  reduced  sales  and 
prices  due  to  the  depression,  and  keen  com- 
petition by  Russian  lumber.  Some  of  the 
mills  in  the  group  resigned  because  they  had 
cut  all  the  lumber  available  to  them;  others 
curtailed  production  by  reason  of  lessening 
demand.  These  conditions  led  to  dissolution 
of  the  association  in  1933. 


Years 


1920-27 
1920-27 
1920-27 
1920-27 
1920-27 
1920-27 
1920-27 
1920-27 
1920-27 
1920-27 
1920-27 
1920-27 


1930-39 
1930-39 
1930-39 


Total  num 

ber  of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1930-39 


1920-33 


I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


195 


120  ASSOCIATIONS'  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Gulf  Pitch  Pine  Export  Association — Continued. 

Members 

Batson-Hatten  Lumber  Co.,  Lyman,  Miss 

C.  &  R.  Lumber  Co.,  Blodgett,  Miss 

Dantzler,  L.  N.,  Lumber  Co.,  Moss  Point,  Miss 
Hines,  Edward,  Yellow  Pine  Trustees,  Lumber- 
ton,  Miss 

Jordan  River  Lumber  Co.,  Kiln,  Miss 

Virgin  Pine  Lumber  Co.,  Piave,  Miss 

Weston,  H.,  Lumber  Co.,  Logtown,  Miss 


Hawkeye    Pearl    Button    Export   Co.,    Muscatine, 
Iowa 

Organized  in  1921  to  sell  in  export  trade  the 
buttons  manufactured  by  the  Hawkeye  Pearl 
Button  Co.,  and  to  cooperate  with  the 
Associated  Button  Exporters  of  America 
(another  Webb  lavt^  group)  the  company 
operated  until  1931,  but  was  then  seriously 
affected  by  Japanese  competition  in  the 
Latin-American  countries,  and  finally  be- 
came dissolved  in  1936. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Hagermann,  C.  C,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

Hawkeye  Pearl  Button  Co.,  Muscatine,  Iowa.. 

Hermann,  F.  W.,  Muscatine,  Iowa _. 

Vetter,  F.  C,  Muscatine,  Iowa 


Years 


Inter-America  Exporters,  Inc.,  New  York 

Organized  in  1935  to  export  fruit  to  Latin- 
American  countries,  the  association  met  with 
difficulties,  especially  restrictions  placed  on 
fruit  imports  by  South  American  countries. 
The  business  was  not  successfully  developed 
and  the  association  became  dissolved  in  1937. 

Members  (stockholders) 


Incorporated,  but  no  stock  issued. 
Directors  were: 

Harkness,  A.  C,  New  York  City... 

Lee,  Florence,  New  York  City 

Lehrer,  Milton  H.,  New  York  City. 

Marder,  Helen,  New  York  City 


International  Steel  Corporation,  New  York 

Organized  in  1918  (as  American  International 
Steel  Corporation,  name  changed  in  1919) 
to  act  as  export  agent  for  a  number  of  steel 
companies,  including  the  Allied  Machinery 
Co.  of  America,  and  G.  Amsinck  &  Co.,  the 
corporation  became  involved  in  litigation, 
and  was  --iissolved  in  1923. 
2.-T7fiJ)— tl— No.  6 14 


1924-33 
1926-30 
1920-33 

1920-31 
1920-21 
1926-33 
1920-33 


Total  num- 
ber of 
membars 


1921-36 
1921-36 
1921-36 
1921-36 


1935-37 
1935-37 
1935-37 
1935-37 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1921-36 


1935-37 


1918-23 


196 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num 

ber  of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


International  Steel  Corporation — Continued. 
Member,  all  stock  held  by — 


American  International  Corp.,  New  York 

Internatioxial  Wood  Naval  -Stores  Export  Corpora- 
tion, Gulfport,  Miss 

Organized  in  1939,  the  corporation  exports  tur- 
pentine and  rosin  (manufactured  by  wood 
distillation).  Some  of  the  members  of  this 
group  were  members  of  the  Wood  Naval 
Stores  Export  Corporation,  which  operated 
under  the  act  from  1935  to  1938. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Alabama  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Mobile,  Ala 

Chemical  Products  Co.,  Laurel,  Miss 

Continental  Turpentine  &  Rosin  Corporation, 
Laurel,  Mies .   

Crosby  Naval  Stores,  Inc.,  Picayune,  Miss 

Dixie  Pine  Products  Co.,  Hattiesburg,  Miss 

Mackie  Pine  Products  Co.,  Covington,  La ' 

Phoenix  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Gulfport,  Miss 

Southern  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Columbia,  Miss  — 


1918-23 


1939 


1939 
1939 

1939 
1939 
1939 
1939 
1939 
1939 


Locomotive  Export  Association,  New  York _. 

Organized  in  1920  for  the  purpose  of  procur- 
ing foreign  business  for  its  members  and  aid- 
ing them  in  the  performance  of  contracts 
for  export  shipment,  the  as.sociation  oper- 
ated successfully  until  1928  in  spite  of  keen 
competition  of  European  builders.  Early 
in  1930,  it  reported  dissolution  by  mutual 
agreement.  One  member,  the  American 
Locomotive  Sales  Corporation,  continued 
to  f?le  papers  under  the  Export  Trade  Act 
until   1939. 

Members 

American  Locomotive  Co.,  New  York.. 

American  Locomotive  Sales  Corp.,  New  York. 

Baldwin  Locomotive  Works,  Philadelphia 

Montreal  Locomotive  Works,  Ltd.,  New  York: 

McKee  Button  Export  Co.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

Organized  in  1921  to  sell  buttons  in  foreign 
markets,  the  company  found  it  difficult  to 
meet  Japanese  competition;  and  was  unable 
to  establish  an  export  business.  It  became 
dissolved  in  1925.  The  company  was  a 
member  of  the  Associated  Button  Exporters 
of  America,  Inc.,  which  filed  papers  under 
the  a6t  from  1921  to  1933. 


1920-29 


1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 


1921  25 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


197 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES-Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


McKee  Button  Export  Co. — Continued. 

Members  (stockholders) 

McKee,  Albert  S.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

McKee,  James  S.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

McKee,  J.  Harold,  Muscatine,. Iowa.. 

Metal  Lath  Export  Association,  The,  New  York... 
This  association  has  been  in  active  operation 
for  the  past  10  years,  developing  export 
trade  in  metal  lath,  for  its  member  com- 
panies. It  reports  that  operation  under  the 
Export  Trade  Act  "provides  an  organiza- 
tion through  which  the  members  are  better 
able  to  meet  foreign  competition  in  foreign 
markets." 

Members 

Berger  Manufacturing  Co.,  The,  Canton,  Ohio.. 

Bostwick  Steel  Lath  Co.,  The,  Niles,  Ohio 

Consolidated    Expanded     Metal    Companies, 

The,  New  York 

Expanded  Metal  Engineering  Co.,  New  York.. 

Kalman  Steel  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

North   Western    Expanded    Metal    Co.,    The, 

Chicago 

Penn  Metal  Co.,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  and  New 

York 

Republic  Steel  Corp.  (Berger  Mfg.  Div.),  New 

York . 

Truscon  Steel  Co.,  New  York 

U.  S.  Gypsum  Co.,  Chicago 


Millers  Export  Association,  Inc.,  The,  Chicago 

Formed  in  1919  to  promote  sales  of  wheat  flour 
to  foreign  Governments,  through  the  U.  S. 
Grain  Corporation,  the  association  ceased 
operation  in  1920,  and  became  dissolved  in 
1922. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Acme-Evans  Co.,  Indianapolis,  Ind 

Acme  Milling  Co.,  Oklahoma  City,  Okla 

Acme  Mills,  Inc.,  The,  Hopkinsville,  Ky 

Akin-Erskine  MiUing  Co.,  Evansville,  Ind 

Allen  &  Wheeler  Co.,  The,  Troy,  Ohio 

Amendt  Milling  Co.,  Monroe,  Mich 

Arkansas    City    Milling    Co.,    Arkansas    City, 

Kans 

Atkinson  Milling  Co.,  Minneapolis -.. 

Attica  Mills,  Attica,  Kans — 

Baldwin,  D.  N.,  Minneapolis 


1921-25 
1921-25 
1921-25 


/ 1929-31 

11937-38 

1929-39 

1929-39 
192^39 
1929-31 

1929-30 

1929-39 

1938-39 
1929-39 
1932-39 


1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-20 

1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1920-21 


10 


160 


1929-39 


1919-22 


198 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Period  of 

Total  num- 

associ- 

Years 

ber  of 

ation 

members 

opera- 
tion 

Millers  Export  Association,  Inc.,  The — Continued. 

Baldwin,  Dwight  M.,  Minneapolis 

1921-22 

Baldwin  Flour  Mills,  Minneapolis   _-    .- 

1919-20 

Ballard  &  Ballard  Co.,  Louisville,  Ky 

1919-22 

Barber  Milling  Co.,  Minneapolis                - - 

1919-20 

Bausman,  Richard  F.,  New  York 

1919 
1919-21 

Bay  State  Milling  Co.,  Boston.       .         _   . 

Bay  State  Milling  Co.,  Winona,  Minn 

1919-22 

Bewley  Mills,  Fort  Worth,  Tex          _   . 

1919-22 

Big  Diamond  Mills  Co.,  Minneapolis        

1919-22 

Blake  Milling  Co.,  Edwardsville,  III 

1919-22 

Blish  Milling  Co.,  Seymour,  Ind- 

1919-22 

Brand-Dunwoody  Milling  Co.,  Joplin,  Mo 

1919-22 

Campbell,  A.  Spottswood,  Brooklyn,  N.  Y 

1919 

Canadian  Mill  &  Elevator  Co.,  El  Reno,  Okla.. 

1919-22 

Cannon  Vallev  Milling  Co.,  Minneapolis 

1919-22 

Cape  County  IVIilling  Co.,  Carthage,  Mo 

1920-21 

Cape  County  Milling  Co.,  Jackson.  Mo 

1919-22 

Cataract  City  Milling  Co.,  Niagara  Falls,  N.  Y. 

1919-22 

Centurv  Milling  Co.,  Minneapolis,    .. 

1919-22 

Chapman  Milling  Co.,  Sherman,  Tex      

1919-22 

Cleveland  Milling  Co.,  Cleveland,  Ohio 

1919-22 

Cole,  H.  C,  Milling  Co., "Chester,  111...    

1919-22 

Colton  Bros.  Co.,  Bellefontaine,  Ohio            -    . 

1919-22 
1919-22 

Commander  Mill  Co.,  Minneapolis- 

Commercial  Milling  Co.,  Detroit 

1919-22 

Consohdated    Flour    Mills    Co.,    Hutchinson, 

Kans 

1919-22 
1919-22 

Cowgill  &  Hill  Milling  Co.,  Carthage,  Mo 

Davis,  J.  G.,  &  Co.,  Rochester,  N.  Y 

1919-22 

Diamond  Mill  Co.,  Sherman,  Tex 

1919-22 
1919-22 

Duluth  Universal  Milling  Co.,  Duluth,  Minn__ 

Dunwoodie,  W.  P.,  Joplin,  Mo 

1920-21 

Eagle  Roller  Mills  Co.,  New  Ulm,  Minn 

1919-22 

Eckhart,  B.  A.,  Milling  Co.,  Chicago 

1919-22 

Empire  Milling  Co.,  Minneapolis 

1919-22 

Enid  Milling  Co.,  Enid,  Okla 

1919-22 

Ervin,  H.  C,  Co.,  St.  Cloud,  Minn 

1919 

Everett-Aughenbaugh  &  Co.,  Waseca,  Minn 

1919-22 

Fant  Milling  Co.,  Sherman,  Tex 

1921-22 

Federal  Mill  &  Elevator  Co.,  Inc.,  Lockport, 

N.  Y. 

1921-22 
1919-21 

Federal  Milling  Co.,  Lockport,  N.  Y 

Frazee,  James,  Milling  Co.,  Baldwinsville,  N.  Y. 

1919-20 

Gambrill,    C.    A.,    Manufacturing   Co.,    Balti- 

more, Md 

1919-22 

Gladnev  Milling  Co.,  Sherman,  Tex 

1919-21 

Gooch  Milling  &  Elevator  Co.,  Lincoln,  Nebr__ 

1919-22 

Great  Northern  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Minneapolis. _ 

1919-22 

Hamilton,  Wm.,  &  Son,  Caledonia,  N.  Y 

1919-22 

1 

Harrison,  J.  Herbert,  Brooklvn,  N.  Y 

1919 

Hormel  Milling  Co.,  Austin,  Minn 

1919-22 
1919-22 

Hubbard  Milling  Co.,  Mankato,  Minn .... 

Hunter  Milling  Co.,  Wellington,  Kans 

1919-22 

Igleheart  Bros.,  Evansville,  Ind 

1919-22 

Imbs,  J.  F.,  Milling  Co.,  St.  Louis,  Mo 

1919-22 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


199 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Period  of 

Total  num- 

associ- 

Years 

ber  of 

ation 

members 

opera- 
tion 

Millers  Export  Association,  Inc.,  The — :Continued. 

International  Milling  Co.,  New  Prague,  Minn.. 

1919-22 

Ismert-Hincke  Milling  Co.,  Kansas  City,  Mo.. 

1919-22 

Jennison,  W.  J.,  Co.,  Minneapolis,  Minn 

1919-22 

Kalispell  Flour  Mill  Co.,  Kalispell,  Mont 

1919-20 

Kalispell  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Great  Falls,  Mont__- 

1921-22 

Kalispell  Milling  Co.,  Great  Falls,  Mont 

Kansas  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Kansas  City,  Mo 

1920-21 

1919-22 

Kansas  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Wichita,  Kans 

1920-21 

Kehlor  Flour  Mills  Co.,  St.  Louis,  Mo 

1919-22 

Kell  Milling  Co.,  Vernon,  Tex 

1919-22 

Kelly,  WiUiam,  Milling  Co.,  Hutchinson,  Kans. 

1919-22 

La  Grange  Mills,  Red  Wing,  Minn 

1919-22 

Larabee  Flour  Mills  Corporation,  Kansas  City, 

Mo 

1919-22 

Lawrenceburg  Roller  Mills  Co.,  Lawrenceburg, 

Ind 

1919-22 
1919-20 

Lea  Milling  Co.,  Wilmington,  Del 

Lee,  H.  D.,  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Salina,  Kans 

1919-22 

Lee,  H.  D.,  Milling  Co.,  Hutchinson,  Kans 

1920-21 

Lexington    Mill   &   Elevator   Co.,    Lexington, 

Nebr - 

1919-22 
1920-21 

Lexington  Milling  Co.,  Lexington,  Nebr 

Lexington  Roller  Mills  Co.,  Lexington,  Ky 

1919-22 

Liberty  Mills,  Nashville,  Tenn 

1919-22 

Listman  Mills,  La  Crosse,  Wis 

1919-20 

Louisville  Milling  Co.,  Louisville,  Ky 

1919-22 

Majestic  Milling  Co.,  Aurora,  Mo 

1919-22 

Maney  Milling  Co.,  Omaha,  Nebr 

1919-22 

Marshall  MiUing  Co.,  Marshall,  Minn 

1919-22 

Mayflower  Mills,  Fort  Wayne,  Ind 

1919-22 

Mennel  Milling  Co.,  Toledo,  Ohio 

1919-22 

Meyer,  John  F.,  &  Sons  Milling  Co.,  St.  Louis.. 

1919-20 

Midland  Flour  Milling  Co.,  Kansas  City,  Mo.. 

1921-22 

Midland  Milling  Co.,  Kansas  City,  Mo 

1919-21 

Mid- West  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Columbus,  Ohio 

1919-21 

Mid- West  Flour  Mills  Co.,  The,  New  York 

1921-22 

Model  Mill  Co.,  Johnson  City,  Tenn 

1919-22 

Monarch  Milling  Co.,  Hutchinson,  Kans 

1919-22 

Montana  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Lewistown,  Mont-. 

1919-22 

Moon,  Geo.  Q.,  Co.,  Inc.,  Binghamton,  N.  Y.. 

1919-22 

Morristown     Flour    Mills    Co.,     Morristown, 

Tenn 

1919-22 
1919-22 

Morten  Milling  Co.,  Dallas,  Tex 

Moseley    &    Motley    Milling    Co.,    Rochester, 

NY 

1919-22 
1919-20 

Mountain  City  Mills  Co.,  Chattanooga,  Tenn. 

National  Milling  Co.,  Toledo,  Ohio 

1919-22 

New   Era   Milling   Co.,   The,   Arkansas   Citv, 

Ark-.^ 

1919-22 

Newton    Milling    &    Elevator    Co.,    Newton, 

Kans 

1919-20 
1919-22 

Niagara  Falls  Milling  Co.,  Buffalo,  N.  Y 

North  Platte  Flour  Mills,  North  Platte,  Nebr.. 

1919-20 

Northwestern   Elevator  &   Milling  Co.,   The, 

Toledo..  Ohio . 

1919-22 

200 


CJONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FOKMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Millers  Export  Association,  Inc.,  The — Continued. 
Oklahoma  City  Mill  &  Elevator  Co.,  Oklahoma 
City 

Oklahoma  Mill  Co.,  Kingfisher,  Okla 

Omaha  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Omaha,  Nebr 

Page,  Thomas,  Milling  Co.,  Topeka,  Kans 

Pillsbury  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Minneapolis 

Plant,  Geo.  P.,  Milling  Co.,  St.  Louis,  Mo 

Quaker  City  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Quaker  Oats  Co.,  Chicago 

Ravenna  ^ills.  Inc.,  The,  Ravenna,  Nebr 

Rea-Patterson  Milling  Co.,  Coffeyville,  Kans-- 

Red  Star  Milling  Co.,  Wichita,  Kans 

Reno  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Hutchinson,  Kans 

Roanoke  City  Mills,  Inc.,  Roanoke,  Va 

Robinson  Milling  Co.,  Salina,  Kans 

Royal  Milling  Co.,  Great  Falls,  Mont 

Russell-Miller  Milling  Co.,  Minneapolis 

Saxony  Mills,  St.  Louis,  Mo 

St.  Paul  Milling  Co.,  St.  Paul,  Minn 

Schultz,  Baujan  &  Co.,  Beardstown,  111 

Shane  Bros.  &  Wilson  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Sheffield-King  Milling  Cd.,  Minneapolis 

Smith,  G.  B.  R.,  Milling  Co.,  Sherman,  Tex-__ 

Smith,  J.  Allen,  &  Co.,  Knoxville,  Tenn 

Spaiks  Milling  Co.,  Alton,  111 

Sparks  Milling  Co.,  Terre  Haute,  Ind 

Stanard-Tilton  Milling  Co.,  Dallas,  Tex 

Stanard-Tilton  Milling  Co.,  Indianapolis 

Stanard-Tilton  Milling  Co.,  St.  Louis.  Mo 

Star  &  Crescent  Milling  Co.,  Chicago 

Stern,  Bernhard  &  Sons,  Inc.,  Milwaukee 

Stickell,  D.  A.,  &  Sons,  Hagerstown,  Md 

Stokes  Milling  Co.,  Watertown,  S.  Dak 

Stott,  David,  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Detroit 

Thatcher,  T.  C,  Oklahoma  City,  Okla 

Thompson  Milling  Co.,  Lockport,  N.  Y 

Thornton  &  Chester  Milling  Co.,  Buffalo,  N.  Y. 

Toledo  Grain  &  Milling  Co.,  Toledo,  Ohio 

Topeka  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Topeka,  Kans 

Updike  Milling  Co.,  Omaha,  Nebr 

Urban,  Geo.,  Milling  Co.,  Buffalo,  N.  Y 

Valier  &  Spies  Milling  Co.,  St.  Louie,  Mo 

Wabasha  Roller  Mill  Co.,  Wabasha,  Minn 

Waco  Mill  &  Elevator  Co.,  Waco,  Tex 

Walnut  Creek  Milling  Co.,  Great  Bend,  Kans 

Washburn-Crosbv  Co.,  Minneapolis 

Washburn-CrosbV  Co.,  Buffalo,  N.  Y 

Weber  Flour  Mills  Corporation,  Salina,  Kans._ 

Wells-Abbott-Nieman  Co.,  Schuvler,  Nebr 

Wichita  Mill  &  Elevator  Co.,  Wichita  Falls, 

Tex 

Williamson  Milling  Co.,  Clay  Center,  Kans 

Wisconsin  Milling  Co.,  Menomonie,  Wis 


1919-20 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-20 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-20 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-20 
1919-20 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-20 
1919-22 
1919-20 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-20 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1921-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-21 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-20 
1919-20 
1919-22 

1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR 


201 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num 

ber  of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Mississippi  Valley  Trading  &  Navigation  Co.,  St. 
Loui?,  Mo 

This  association  was  formed  in  1920  with  the 
intention  of  selling  products  of  the  Mississippi 
Valley  in  foreign  markets,  including  steel, 
dry  goods,  shoes,  paper,  furniture,  flour,  rioe, 
and  hardware.  It  was  found,  however,  that 
Webb  law  groups  can  operate  to  better  ad- 
vantage when  formed  to  sell  1  commodity 
rather  than  an  assortment  of  unrelated  prod- 
ucts. The  company  was  therefore  not  suc- 
cessful, and  liquidation  was  finally  completed 
in  1923. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Blanke,  C.  F.,  Tea  &  Coffee  Co.,  St.  Louis,  Mo.. 

Brown  Shoe  Co.,  St.  Louis 

Conrades,  J.  H.,  St.  Louis 

Conrades  Manufacturing  Co.,  St.  Louis 

Cramer,  E.  F.,  St.  Louis 

Cramer,  F.  Ernest,  St.  Louis 

Ely  &  Walker  D.  G.  Co.,  St.  Louis 

Faust,  E.  A..  St.  Louis 

Fisher,  Wm.,  St.  Louis 

Folk,  Jos.  W.,  Washington,  D.  C,  and  St.  Louis. 

Handlan,  E.  W.,  St.  Louis 

Karbe,  Otto  F.,  St.  Louis 


Koken  Companies,  St.  Louis .. 

Lampkin,  E.  P.,  St.  l/ouis 

Lueking,  A.  C,  St.  Louis 

Moloney  Elec.  Co.,  St.  Louis 

Molonev,  T.  O.,  St.  Louis 

O'Neil,  John  F.,  St.  Louis 

Rand,  Frank  C,  St.  Louis 

St.  Louis  Boat  &  Engineering  Co.,  St.  Louis. 

Sharp,  Chas.  E.,  St.  Louis 

Sutter,  Charles,  St.  Louis 

Tarlton,  Wm.  E.,  St.  Louis 

Van  Schoiack,  T.  W.,  St.  Louis 

Waltke,  Louis  H.,  St.  Louis 


Namusa  Corporation  (at  first  called  Namusa  South 
American  Corporation),  New  York 

Formed  in  1919  by  the  National  Association  of 
Manufacturers  of  the  United  States  of 
America  (from  the  initials  of  which  the  asso- 
ciation derived  its  name  "Namusa")  its  in- 
tention was  to  sell  in  foreign  markets,  prod- 
ucts of  the  manufacturers  that  were  members 
of  the  trade  association,  serving  as  export 
agent  on  a  commission  basis.  The  plan  was 
not  successful,  however,  perhaps  because  so 
many  unrelated  products  were  inclut'.ed 
among  the  products  of  the  members.     As  in 


1920-21 
1920-21 
1921-23 
1920-21 
1920-21 
1921-23 
1920-21 
1921-23 
1921-23 
1920-23 
1920-23 
1920-23 

/1920-21 

U923 
1920-23 
1921-23 
1920-21 
1921-23 
1920-23 
1920-23 
1920-21 
1920-23 
1920-23 
1921-23 
1921-22 
1920-23 


25 


1920-23 


56 


1919-22 


202 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Namusa  Corporation — Continued. 

the  case  of  the  Mississippi  Valley  Trading 
Co.,  it  was  found  better  to  organize  Webb 
law  groups  on  a  commodity  basis,  to  sell  only 
related  products. 

Members  {stockholders} 

Albemarle    Paper    Manufacturing    Co.,    The, 
Richmond,  Va 

American  Aniline  Pi  oducts,  Inc.,  New  York 

American  Belting  Companies,  Texas,  Md 

American  Fork  &  Hoe  Co.,  Cleveland 

Beck  with  Co.,  The,  Dowagiac,  Mich 

Benedict  Manufacturing  Co.,  The,  East  Syra- 
cuse, N.  Y 

Bethlehem  Fabricators,  Inc.,  Bethlehem,  Pa 

Blaw-Knox  Co.,  Pittsburgh 

Blish  Milling  Co.,  Seymour,  Ind 

Brown,  Chas.  H.,  Paint  Co.,  The,  Brooklyn, 

N.  Y .- 

Carnes  Artificial  Limb  C  •.,  Kansas  City,  Mo 

Clover  Leaf  Milling  Co.,  Wellington,  Mo 

Dexter  Yarn  Co.,  Pawtucket,  R.  I 

Dicks-David  Co.,  New  York__ 

Dungan,  Hood  &  Co.,  Inc.,  Philadelphia 

Economy  Ink  Co.,  Cincinnati 

Excelsior  Hardware  Co.,  The,  Stamford,  Conn_ . 

Fletcher  Works,  Inc.,  Philadelphia 

Hale,  John  M.-Boardman,  Inc.,  New  York 

Hays,  Daniel,  Co.,  The,  Gloversville,  N.  Y 

Heiler  Brothers  Co.,  Newark,  N.  J 

Hill-Smith  Metal  Goods  Co.,  The,  Boston 

Hoggson  &  Pettis  Manufacturing  Co.,  The,  New 

Haven,  Conn 

Howlett  &  Hockmeyer  Co.,  New  York 

Hydraulic  Steel  Co.,  The,  Cleveland 

Inland  Motor  Truck  Co.,  Evansville,  Ind 

Kalamazoo    Motors    Corporation,    Kalamazoo, 

Mich 

Lowell  Paper  Tube  Corporation,  Lowell,  Mass. 

Meese  &  Gottfried  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Miller  Saw-Trimmer  Co.,  Pittsburgh.' 

National  Milling  Co.,  Toledo,  Ohio 

Niagara  Machine  &  Tool  Co.,  Buffalo,  N.  Y 

Northern  Paper  Mills,  Green  Bay,  Wis 

Ogden,  ,T.  Edward,  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Patton  Paint  Co.,  Milwaukee 

Pekin  Cooperage  Co.,  Pekin,  IlL .. 

Piqua  Hosiery  Co..  The,  Piqua,  Ohio 

Plumb,  Fayette  R.,  Inc.,  Philadelphia 

Read  Machinery  Co.,  Inc.,  York,  Pa 

Rice,  A.  H.,  Co!,  Pittsfield,  Mass 

Rowe  Calk  &  Chain  Co.,  The,  Plantsville,  Conn. 
Schmidt  &  Ault  Paper  Co.,  York,  Pa 


1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 

1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1920-21 

1919 

1919-22 

1920-21 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1920-21 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1920-22 

1920-22 

1919-21 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1920-21 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919 

1919-21 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 


203 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Namusa  Corporation — Continued. 

Severance,  S.,  Manufacturing  Co.,  Glassport,  Pa. 
Smith  &  Hemenway  Co.,  Inc.,  Irvington,  N.  J_.. 

Sowers  Manufacturing  Co.,  Buffalo,  N.  Y 

Standard  Varnish  Works,  New  York 

Tagliabue,  C.  J.,  Manufacturing  Co.,  Brooklyn, 

N .  Y '. : . . . 

Taylor  &  Fenn  Co.,  The,  Hartford,  Conn 

Urschel-Bates  Valve  Bag  Co.,  Toledo,  Ohio 

Valve  Bag  Co.,  Toledo,  Ohio 

West   Haven    Manufacturing   Co.,  The,   New 

Haven,  Conn ^ 

Weston    Electrical    Instrument    Co.,    Newark, 

N.  J 

White  &  WycofT  Manufacturing  Co.,  Holyoke, 

Mass 1 

Will  &  Baumer  Candle  Co.,  Syracuse,  N.  Y 

Willey,  C.  A.,  Co.,  Long  Island  City,  N.  Y 

Wood  Shovel  &  Tool  Co.,  Piqua,  Ohio 


Naval  Stores  Export  Corporation,  New  Orleans,  La.. 
Organized  in  1923  to  e.xport  naval  stores  (rosins 
and  turpentines  of  all  kinds),  the  association 
operated  successfully  for  several  years.  It 
reported  that  selling  costs  were  reduced 
through  cooperative  action ;  the  central  office 
was  able  to  quote  on  larger  orders;  the  agents 
abroad  developed  new  markets.  But  the 
members'  supply  became  depleted,  several  of 
the  companies  discontinued  entirely,  and  the 
few  remaining  found  exportation  imprac- 
ticable. The  association  was  therefore  dis- 
solved in  1930. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Avera   Naval   Stores  Co.,    Biloxi,    Miss,,    and 
New  Orleans 

Batson  &  Hatten  Lumber  Co.,  Lyman,  Miss 

Batson-McGehee  &  Co.,  Millard,  Miss 

Bcntley  Naval  Stores  Co.,  New  Orleans 

Betts  Naval  Stores  Co.,  New  Orleans 

Blodgett  Naval  Stores  Co.,  New  Orleans 

Bogalusa  Turpentine  Co.,  Bogalusa,  La 

Bullard,  Sellers  &  Co.,  De  Funiack  Springs  and 

Crestview,  Fla 

Cady  Lumber  Co.,  New  Orleans 

Canal    Bank    &    Trust    Co.    (Trustees),    New- 
Orleans  

Chipley,     Buckner     (Gillican-Chipley),     New 

Orleans . 

Eastman-Gardiner  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Laurel, 

Miss.,  and  New  Orleans,  La 

Finkbine  Lumber  Co.,  Jackson,  Miss 


1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919 

1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-20 
1920-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 
1920-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 


1923-26 
1928-30 
192&-30 

fl923 

11926-30 
1923 
1926-30 
1925-30 

1923-30 
1923-24 

1927-30 

1927-30 

1923-30 
1923-28 


39 


1923-30 


204 


COJSrOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Naval  Stores  Export  Corporation — Continued. 

FuUerton  Naval  Stores  Co.,  New  Orleans 

Gay-Hamill  Co.,  Biloxi,  Miss 

Gillican-Chipley  Co.,  New  Orleans 

Gillican,  W.  B.,  New  Orleans 

Goodyear  Lumber  Co.,  Picayune,  Miss 

Great  Southern  Lumber  Co.,  Bogalusa,  La 

Hines,    Edw.,   Yellow   Pine   Co.,   Lumberton, 

Miss. 

Industrial  Lumber  Co.,  Elizabeth,  La 

Jackson  Lumber  Co.,  Lockhart,  La 

Kaul    Lumber    Co.,    Birmingham,    La.,    and 

Biloxi,  Miss 

Kirby  Lumber  Co.,  Houston,  Tex 

Lake  Charles  Naval  Stores  Co.,  New  Orleans.. 
Lake   Wales   Naval   Stores   Co.,   Jacksonville, 

Orlando,  and  Lake  Wales,  Fla.,  and  New 

Orleans,  La 

Natalbany  Lumber  Co.,  Hammond,  La 

New  Orleans  Naval  Stores  Co.,  New  Orleans.. 
Newman,  J.  J.,  Lumber  Co.,  Brookhaven,  Miss. 
Newton,   J.   B.,   Turpentine   Co.,   Poplarville, 

Miss 

Newton  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Poplarville,  Miss  — 

Phelps,  R.  R.,  New  Orleans 

Pringle,  E.  M.,  Naval  Stores  Co.,  McNary,  La- 
Producers  Turpentine  Co..  Elizabeth,  La 

Quitman  Naval  Stores  Co.,  New  Orleans 

Reimers,  F.  W.  (trustee),  Haramond,  La 

Rosa  Turpentine  Co.,  Picayune,  Miss 

Vernon  Parish  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Kurthwood 

and  New  Orleans,  La 

Western  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Houston,  Tex.,  and 

New  Orleans,  La 


Nogales  Garbanzo  Association,  Nogales,  Ariz 

Organized  in  1921  to  dispose  of  a  supply  of 
garbanzos  (chick  peas),  it  became  dissolved 
when  the  stocks  were  exhausted,  in  1922. 

Members 

First  National  Bank  of  Nogales,  Nogales,  Ariz. 

Grace,  W.  R.,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Nogales  National  Bank,  Nogales,  Ariz 

Ocharan,  Oscar,  Nogales,  Ariz 

Salido,  Ildefonso,  Nogales,  Ariz 

Sonora  Bank  &  Trust  Co.,  The,  Nogales,  Ariz. 

Northwest  Dried  Fruit  Export  Association,  Port- 
land, Oreg 

Formed  in  1927  to  ship  dried  fruit  from  the 
Pacific  Northwest,  this  association  has  oper- 
ated successfully,  reporting  as  its  outstand- 
ing advantages  uniform  export  sales  con- 
tracts, uniform  rules  for  export,  and  ability 


1926-30 
1923-30 
1923-30 
1927-30 
1923-26 
1923-25 
1923-30 

1923 
1923-30 

1923-28 
1923-26 
1923-30 


1923-30 
1923-27 
1923-26 
1923-30 

1923-30 

1928-30 

1927-30 

1923 

1923-30 

1923-26 

1927-30 

1923 

1923-30 

1923, 
1926-30 


1921-22 

1921-22 

1922 

1921-22 

1921-22 

1922 


1921-22 


53 


1927-39 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR 


205 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Northwest  Dried  Fruit  Export  Association — Con. 
to  secure  payment  of  the  members'  drafts 
drawn  on  foreign  buyers  who  have  become 
delinquent. 

Members 

Merchants'  Division: 

AbelingGeo.,  Co.,  San  Francisco 1928-39 

AUen,  C.  E.,  Seattle 1928-35 

Anderson  &  Miskin,  Ltd.,  Seattle 1928-31 

Atkins,  Kroll  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 1934-39 

Balfour,   Guthrie  &  Co.,  Ltd.,  Portland, 

Greg 1927-28 

1934^39 

Bocker  European  Trading  Co.,  Seattle 1930-31 

California  Fruit  Selling  Co.,  San  Francisco.  1927-36 
Canadian  International  Corp.,  Vancouver, 

B.  C 1929-30 

Cederwall,  Tver  H.,  Co.,  Seattle 1936-38 

Cleveland,  Ira,  Yakima,  Wash 1936-39 

Cron  &  Dehn,  Inc.,  Seattle '  1927-30 

Davis  &  Wear,  Inc. ,  Seattle 1 927-3 1 

Evaporated  Fruits,  Inc.,  Selah,  Wash 1931-33 

Field,  Walter  M.,  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 1927-39 

General  Commercial  Co.,  Inc.,  The,  San 

Francisco 1927-31 

Gomperts,  Jack,  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 1935-39 

Grell,  E.  F.,  &  Co.,  Seattle 1931-35 

Grothe,  Schmidt  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 1935-39 

Hall,  Harry,  &  Co.,  Inc.,  San  Francisco 1927-39 

Kelly  Bros.  Co.,  Inc.,  Hood  River,  Oreg 1936-38 

Macdonald,  Andrews  Co.,  Portland,  Greg-  _  1939 

North  Pacific  Sales  Co.,  Seattle 1928-36 

O'Malley-Abeling  Co.,  San  Francisco 1927-28 

Otis,  McAllister  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 1928-39 

Peabody,  Henry  W.,  &  Co.   of  London, 

Ltd.,  Seattle 1935-39 

Root,  G.  B.,  &  Co.,  Portland,  Oreg 1927-30 

Sievers,  Paul  F.  L.,  San  Francisco 1939 

Triton  Co.,  The,  Seattle 1927-28 

Wilbur-Ellis  Co.,  San  Francisco 1930-39 

Wilcox-Hayes  Co.,  The,  Portland,  Oreg...  1927-38 
Packers'  Division: 

Allen  Fruit  Co.,  Salem,  Oreg 1927-39 

California     Packing     Corporation,     San 

Francisco . 1927-39 

Catz    American    Co.    of    California,    San 

Francisco 1934-35 

Consolidated  Packing  Co.,  San  Francisco..  1935-39 

Drager  Fruit  Co.,  Salem,  Oreg 1927-29 

Dundee    Fruit    Growers   &   Packers   Asso- 
ciation, Dundee,  Oreg 1930-39 

Ehrman,  Mason,  &  Co.,  Portland,  Oreg...  1927-28 

Evaporated  Fruits,  Inc.,  Selah,  Wash 1927-28 

Gile,  H.  S.,  &  Co.,  Salem,  Oreg. 1927-39 


206 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Period  of 

Total  num- 

associ- 

Years 

ber  of 

ation 

members 

opera- 
tion 

Northwest  Dried  Fruit  Export  Association — Con. 

Packer's  Division — Continued. 

Hogue,  F.  H.,  Payette,  Idaho 

1932-39 

North    Pacific    Cooperative    Prune    Ex- 

change, Portland,  Greg 

1927-39 

Paulus  Bros.  Packing  Co.,  Salem,  Greg 

1927-39 

Paulus,  Rob't  C,  &  Co.,  Salem,  Greg 

1927 

Radovan    Dehydrating   Fruit   Co.,    Cash- 

mere, Wash 

1927-28 

Rosenberg  Bros.  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

1927-39 

Ross  Packing  Co.,  Selah,  Wash 

1933-39 

Scotts  Mills  Packing  Co.,  Salem,  Greg 

1931-34 

South  Douglas  Cooperative  Prune  Grow- 

ers' Pool,  Myrtle  Creek,  Greg 

1927 

Tracy,  J.  G.,  &  Co.,  Dallas,  Greg 

1927-39 

Valley  Evaporating  Co.,  Yakima,  Wash... 

1933-39 

Washington  Dehydrated  Food  Co.,  Yak- 

ima, Wash 

1927-39 

Wa.shington    Growers    Packing    Corpora- 

tion, Vancouver,  Wash 

1927-39 

Willamette     Valley     Prune     Association, 

Salem,  Greg 

1927-39 

Northwest  Lumber  Exporters'  Association,  Seattle, 

Wash 

26 

1929-31 

Organized  in  1929  to  ship  lumber  to  foreign 

countries,  the  association  did  some  prelimi- 

nary work,  but  a  number  of  its  members 

decided  to  join  the  Douglas  Fir  Export  Co., 

an  older  group  operating  under  the  act.     The 

Northwest  association  therefore  became  dis- 

solved. 

Members 

Anacortes  Lumber  &  Box  Co.,  Anacortes,  Wash. 

1929-30 

Anderson  &  Middleton  Lumber  Co.,  Aberdeen, 

Wash 

1929-31 

Bay  City  Lumber  Co.,  Aberdeen,  Wash 

1929-31 

Bissell  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle 

1929-31 
1929-31 

Bolcom  Canal  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle 

Bryant  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle 

1929-31 

Buchanan  Lumber  Co.,  Glympia,  Wash 

1930-31 

Canyon  Lumber  Co.,  Everett,  Wash 

1929-31 

Clark  &  Wilson  Lumber  Co.,  Linnton,  Greg 

1929-31 

Clark  Nickerson  Lumber  Co.,  Everett,  Wash.. 

1929-31 

Des  Chutes  River  Sawmills,  Glympia,  Wash  — 

1930-31 

Duwamish  l.umj^er  Co.,  Seattle 

1929-31 

Eclipse  Mill  Co.,  Everett,  Wash 

1929-31 

Elliott  Bay  Mill  Co.,  Seattle 

1929-31 

Grays  Harbor  Lumber  Co.,  Hoquiam,  Wash... 

1929-30 

Long  Bell  Lumber  Co.,  Longview,  Wash 

1929-31 

Glympia  Harbor  Lumber  Co.,  Glympia,  Wash. 

1930-31 

Reed  Mill  Co.,  Shelton,  Wash 

1930-31 
1929-31 

Seattle  Export  Lumber  Co.,  Seattle 

Sibley  Mills  Lumber  Co.,  Portland,  Greg 

1929-31 

Springer  Mill  Co.,  Glympia,  Wash 

1930-31 

i 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEK 


207 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES-^Continued 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Northwest  Lumber  Exporter's  Association — Con. 

Stimson  Mill  Co.,  Seattle 

Stimson  Timber  Co.,  Seattle 

Tumwater  Lumber  Mills  Co.,  Olympia,  Wash._ 
Washington  Lumber  &  Spar  Co.,  Renton,  Wash- 
Washington  Veneer  Co.,  Olympia,  Wash 


1929-31 
1929-31 
1930-31 
1929-30 
1930-31 


Pacific  Flour  Export  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

The  association  was  formed  in  1924  to  ship  flour 
to  foreign  countrievS,  especially  the  Orient. 
Competition  from  abroad  was  keen,  and  it 
was  reported  that  except  for  operation  of  the 
group  through  one  selling  organization  there 
would  be  loss  to  the  mills.  The  association 
was  at  first  prosperous;  there  seemed  to  be  a 
demand  abroad  for  low-grade  flour.  But 
exports  were  later  affected  by  increased  pro- 
duction of  wheat  in  Canada  and  lower  prices 
on  the  Canadian  exports  of  flour.  Increased 
capacity  of  flour  mills  in  Japan  and  China 
also  led  to  demand  in  those  countries  for 
wheat  instead  of  flour.  The  association  was 
inactive  for  several  years,  and  was  finally 
dissolved  in  1938. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Albers  Bros.  Milling  Co.,  Portland,  Oreg 

Alexander,  A.,  Wilbur,  Wash 

Allen,  W.  S.,  Seattle 

Baumann,  L.  P.,  Seattle 

Beer,  Melvin  D.,  The  Dalles,  Oreg 

Big  Bend  Milling  Co.,  Davenport,  Wash 

Burke,  F.  B.,  Portland,  Oreg 

Centennial  Flouring  Mills  Co.,  Seattle ^ 

Centennial  Mill  Co.,  Seattle 

Collins  Flouring  Mills,  Pendleton,  Oreg 

Columbia  River  Milling  Co.,  Wilbur,  Wash 

Crown  Mills,  Portland,  Oreg . 

Fisher  Flouring  Mills  Co.,  Seattle 

Fisher,  O.  D.,  Seattle 

Jackson,  H.  V.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Johnson,  O.  C,  Portland,  Oreg 

Konnewick  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Kennewick,  Wash_ 

Leonard,  E.  H.,  Waitsburg,  Wash 

Lilly,  Chas.  H.,  Co.,  Seattle 

McCoy,  E.  O.,  The  Dalles,  Oreg 

Miller  Flour  Mills,  Yakima,  Wash 

Noveltv  Mill  Co.,  Seattle 

Pattullo,  D.  A.,  Portland,  Oreg 

Peacock  Mil!  Co.,  The,  Freewater,  Oreg -_ 

Pendleton  Flouring  Mills,  Pendleton,  Oreg 

Pioneer  Flouring  Mills  Co.,  Island  City,  Oreg 

Pomeroy  Flouring  Mills  Co.,  Pomeroy,  Wash 

Pomeroy  Warehouse  &  Milling  Co.,  Pomerov, 
Wash .'-. 


1924-38 
1924-38 
1983-38 
1924-38 
1933-38 
1925-38 
1924-33 
1933-38 
1924-33 
1924-38 
1924-38 
1924-38 
1924-38 
1924-33 
1933-38 
1933-38 
1924-38 
1924-38 
1924-38 
1924-33 
1924-38 
1924-38 
1924-33 
1924-38 
1925-30 
1 924-38 
1924-30 

1930-38 


37 


208 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Pacific  Flour  Export  Co. — Continued. 

Portland  Flour  Mills  Co.,  Portland,  Greg 

Preston-Shaffer  Milling  Co.,  Waitsburg,  Wash. 

Rose  City  Flour  Mills,  Portland,  Greg 

Shull,  F.  L.,  Portland,  Greg 

Sperry  Flour  Co.,  Taconia,  Wash 

Spokane  Flour  Mills,  Spokane,  Wash 

VoUmer  Clearwater  Co.,  Ltd.,  Lewiston,  Idaho. 
Wasco   Warehouse    Milling   Co.,   The   Dalles, 

Greg 

Western  Milling  Co.,  Pendleton,  Greg 


Pacific  Forest  Industries,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Organized  in  1935  to  sell  plywood  for  shipment 
to  foreign  countries,  the  association  includes 
two  classes  of  members: 

Stockholders 

Aberdeen  Plywood  Co.,  Aberdeen,  Wash 

Aircraft  Plywood  Corporation,  Seattle,  Wash.. 

Capitol  Plywood  Co.,  Olympia,  Wash 

Elliott  Bay  Mill  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Harbor  Plywood  Corporation,-  Hoquiam,  Wash. 
M    and    M    Plywood    Corporation,    Portland, 

Greg 

Glympia  Veneer  Co.,  Glympia,  Wash 

Oregon- Washington    Plywood    Co.,    Tacoma, 

Wash 

Plylock  Corporation,  The,  Portland,  Greg 

Robinson  Mfg.  Co.,  Everett,  Wash _.. 

United  States  Plywood  Corporation,  Seattle, 

Wash 

Vancouver  Plywood  &  Veneer  Co.,  Vancouver, 

Wash 

Washington  Veneer  Co.,  Olympia,  Wash 

Wheeler  Osgood  Sales    Corporation,  Tacoma, 

Wash 

Associate  Members 

Buffelen  Lumber  Manufacturing  Co.,  Tacoma, 
Wash 

Lyle,  Donald  W.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

McCleary,    Henry,    Timber    Co.,    McCIeary, 

Wash .. 

Northwest  Door  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Peterman  Manufacturing  Co..  Tacoma,  Wash.. 

Smith  Wood  Products,  Inc.,  Portland,  Greg 

West  Coast  Plywood  Co.,  Aberdeen,  Wash 

Pacific  Fresh  Fruit  Export  Association,  San  Fran- 
cisco   

Organized  in  1937  to  export  fresh  fruit  to 
foreign  countries,  the  association  reports  that 
it  has  improved  the  members'  relations  with 


Years 


1924-38 

1924-38 

1924-25 

1924 

1924-38 

1924-38 

1924-38 

1924-38 
1930-38 


1935-39 
1935-37 
1935-39 
1935-39 
1935-39 

1935-39 
1935-39 

1935-39 
1935-39 
1935-39 

1937-39 

1935-39 
1935-39 

1935-39 


1938-39 
1938-39 

1938-39 
1938-39 
1938-39 
1938-39 
1938-39 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


21 


13 


1935-39 


1937-39 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 


209 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Pacific  Fresh  Fruit  Export  Association — Con. 

domestic  suppliers  and  with  foreign  buyers; 
it  has  reduced  credit  losses,  and  effected  a 
marked  reduction  in  tb-  number  of  claims 
received  from  foreign  customei's. 

Members 

Battat  Import  &  Export  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Connell  Bros.,  Co.,  Ltd.,  San  Francisco 

Demartinl,  John,  Co.,  Inc.,  San  Francisco 

Fidelity  Trading  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Getz  Bros.  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Levy,  A.,  &  J.  Zentner  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Liberty  Gold  Fruit  Co.,  San  Francisco 

McXear,  J.  A.,  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Otis,  McAllister  &  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Pacific  Produce  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Seattle  Pacific  Products  Co.,  Seattle 

Sunset  Produce  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Wileman  Bros.  &  Elliott,  San  Francisco 


Years 


Pan-American  Trading  Co.,  New  York 

This  was  an  export  company  selling  miscel- 
laneous products  in  foreign  countries,  es- 
pecially in  the  South  American  trade.  It 
filed  papers  with  the  Commission  for  several 
years,  but  was  not  really  a  combination,  and 
for  that  reason  withdrew  from  operation 
under  the  act  in  1927. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Isaacs,  Henry,  New  York 

Isaacs,  Herman,  New  York 

Lsaacs,  Ruf us,  New  York 

Isaacs,  Mrs.  Ruf  us,  New  York 

Kadane,  Jos.  C,  New  York 

Leavenworth,  David,  New  York 


Pencil  Industry  Export  Association,  New  York 

The  association  was  formed  in  1939  to  ship  to 
foreign  countries:  pencils,  pens,  including  me- 
chanical pencils  and  pens,  penholders,  and 
all  other  forms  of  writing  and  marking  in- 
struments and  related  stationery  items. 

Members 

American  Lead  Pencil  Co.,  The,  Hoboken,  N.  J. 
Dixon,  Joseph,  Crucible  Co.,  Jersey  City,  N.  J. 

Eagle  Pencil  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Faber,  Eberhard,  Pencil  Co.,  The,  Brooklyn, 
NY 


1937-38 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-38 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 


1925-27 
1919-27 
1919-22 
1922-27 
1919-22 
1925-26 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1919-27 


1939 


210 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS'  F0RM5:D  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Pennsylvania   Millers   Export   Association,    Phila- 
delphia  

The  association  was  formed  in  1919  to  meet 
conditions  which  arose  during  the  period 
when  the  United  States  Grain  Corporation 
was  buying  flour  for  export  in  large  quanti- 
ties. It  became  dissolved  when  the  work  of 
the  Grain  Corporation  was  ended. 

Members  (stockholders) 


Adler  Bros.,  Altoona,  Pa 

Barnitz,  Wra.  B.,  Barnitz,  Pa 

Brackbill,  ElHs  B.,  Gap,  Pa 

Cannonsburg  Milling  Co.,  Cannonsburg,  Pa__ 

City  Flour  Co.,  Inc.,  Muncy,  Pa 

Cochranton  Milling  Co.,  Cochran  ton,  Pa 

Curry,  John  B.,  Sons,  Palmyra,  Pa 

Dayton  Milling  Co.,  Towanda,  Pa 

Ellis,  David,  &  Sons,  Indiana,  Pa 

Fleming  &  Shollenberger,  Hepburnville,  Pa 

Lio,  Antonio,  &  Sons,  Hahfax,  Pa 

McDonald  Milling  Co.,  McDonald,  Pa 

Millersburg  Milling  Co.,  Millersburg,  Pa 

Patterson  Milling  Co.,  Saltsburg,  Pa 

Rachau,  J.  L.,  Clintondale,  Pa 

Washington  Milling  Co. ,  Washington,  Pa 

Weiss,  Chas.  Z.,  Avon,  Pa — 

Williams  Bros.,  Port  Matilda,  Pa 


Phosphate  Export  Association,  New  York 

Operating  successfully  since  1919,  the  associa- 
tion ships  pebble  phosphate  rock  to  foreign 
markets.  It  had  cooperative  relationship 
with  Florida  Pebble  Phosphate  Export  As- 
sociation, and  became  consolidated  with 
that  group  in  1933  (see  Florida  Pebble  Phos- 
phate Export  Association) ;  has  also  had  co- 
operative agreements  with  Florida  Hard  Rock 
Phosphate  Export  Association.  It  reports 
the  following  advantages  obtained  by  opera- 
tion as  a  Webb  law  group:  Uniform  sales 
terms,  standardization  of  grades,  reduction 
of  selling  expenses,  saving  on  ocean  freight 
and  insurance,  reduction  of  credit  losses, 
elimination  of  unfair  claims  from  buyers, 
stable  export  prices  at  profitable  levels,  and 
better  abilitv  to  meet  foreign  competition  in 
the  export  field;  "only  by  combining  under 
the  Webb  law  and  acting  as  a  unit,  can  the 
members  meet  the  competition  cf  foreign 
producers."  The  association  adds  that 
"This  Law  seems  to  adequately  meet  our 
nieeds  in  every  respect." 


Years 


191^20 
1919-20 
191&-20 
1919-20 
1919-20 
1919-20 
191^20 
1919-20 
1919-20 
1919-20 
1919-20 
1919-20 
1919-20 
1919-20 
1919-20 
1919-20 
1919-20 
1919-20 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


18 


10 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1919-20 


1919-39 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


211 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Phosphate  Export  Association — Continued. 
Members 


The, 


American    Agricultural    Chemical    Co. 

New  York 

American  Cyanamid  Co.,  New  York 

Coronet  Phosphate  Co.,  New  York 

International  Agricultural   Corporation,  New 
York . 

Morris  Fertilizer  Co.,  branch  of  Armour  Fer- 
tilizer Works,  Chicago 

Ore  &  Chemical  Corporation,  The,  New  York.. 
Phosphate  Mining  Co.,  New  York 


Southern  Phosphate  Corporation,  Baltimore. 
Swift  &  Co.,  Chicago 

Swift  &  Co.  Fertilizer  Works,  Chicago 


Pioneer  Pearl  Button  Export  Corporation,  Pough- 
keepsie,  N.  Y 

Organized  to  export  products  of  the  Pioneer 
Pearl  Button  Co.,  the  association  operated 
for  several  years  but  found  it  impossible  to 
compete  in  foreign  markets  with  Japanese 
and  European  producers.  It  therefore  be- 
came dissolved  in  1929. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Clark,  R.  H.,  Poughkeepsie,  N.  Y 

Ethal.  Hazel  A.,  Poughkeepsie,  N.  Y 

Ethal,  H.  J.  W.,  Poughkeepsie,  N.  Y.... 

Huttig,  H.  W.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

Pioneer  Pearl  Button  Co.,  Poughkeepsie,  N.  Y.. 

Pipe  Fittings  and  Valve  Export  Association,  The, 
Philadelphia 

Organized  in  1919  to  ship  pipe  fittings  and 
valves  to  foreign  markets,  the  association  has 
operated  successfully  for  over  20  years. 
Among  advantages  reported  are  standardi- 
zation of  products  and  terms  of  sale  in  ex- 
port shipments,  elimination  of  trade  abuses 
in  the  export  field,  interchange  of  experience 
concerning  conditions  in  foreign  markets, 
and  the  benefits  of  cooperation  in  develop- 
new    markets. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Chapman  Valve  &  Manufacturing  Co.,  Indian 
Orchard,  Mass 

Crane  Export  Corporation,  Long  Island  City, 
N.  Y 

Flagg,  Stanley  G..  &  Co.,  Inc.,  Philadelphia ..- 
General  Fire  Extinguisher  Co.,  Providence,  R.  I. 

257769— 41— No.  6 15 


1929-39 
1929-39 
1919-27 

1919-39 

1922-24 
1929-39 
1919-26 
1933-39 
1920-39 
1938-39 
I4933-37 


1923-26 
1926-29 
1923-29 
1923-29 
1922 


1935-37 

1933-39 
1919-39 
1923-34 


5  1922-29 


19 


191&-39 


212 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEJl 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num 

ber  of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Pipe  Fittings  and  Valve  Export  Association,  The — 
Continued. 
Grabler  Manufacturing.  Co.,  Cleveland,  Ohio.. 

Grinnell  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York . 

Jarecki  Manufacturing  Co.,  Erie,  Pa 

Jenkins  Bros.,  Bridgeport,  Conn 

Kelly  &  Jones  Co.,  New  York 

Kennedy   Valve   Manufacturing   Co.,    Elmira, 

NY 

Kuhns  Bros.  Co.,  Dayton,  Ohio 

Lunkenheimer  Co.,  Cincinnati,  Ohio 

Malleable  Iron  Fittings  Co.,  Branford,  Conn._. 
McNab   &   Harlin    Manufacturing   Co.,    New 

York 

Nelson  Valve  Co.,  Chestnut  Hill,  Pa 

Pittsburgh  Valve  &  Fittings  Co.,  Barberton, 

Ohio 

Pratt  &  Cady  Co.,  Inc.,  Hartford,  Conn 

Ravena  Iron  Co.,  Ravena,  N.  Y 

Walworth  Manufacturing  Co , 

Walworth  Co.,  Inc.,  and 

Walworth  International  Co.  (organized  to  han- 
dle export  business  of  the  manufacturing 
conapany),  Boston,  Mass.,  and  New  York 

Plate  Glass  Export  Corporation,  Pittsburgh,  Pa 

Organized  in  December  1935  to  export  plate 
glass  to  foreign  markets,  the  association  is 
operating  successfully,  reporting  that  its 
chief  advantage  has  been  cooperation  in 
prices  and  trade  customs  for  export  ship- 
ment, thereby  enabling  the  members  to  meet 
the  competition  of  European  manufacturers; 
and  that  "We  continue  in  our  belief  that  the 
organization  under  the  Export  Trade  Act  is 
beneficial  to  the  industry." 

Members  {stockholders) 

Franklin  Glass  Corporation,  Butler,  Pa 

Libbey-Owens-Ford  Glass  Co.,  Toledo,  Ohio 

Pittsburgh  Plate  Glass  Co.,  Pittsburgh 


Potash  Export  Association,  Inc.,  New  York 

Organized  in  1938  for  the  purpose  of  exporting 
potash  (potassium  chloride,  potassium  sul- 
fate, sulfate  of  potash  magnesia,  kainit,  and 
manure  salts.) 

Members  (stockholders) 

American    Potash    &    Chemical    Corporation, 

New  York , 

Potash  Co.  of  America,  Denver,  Colo 

United  States  Potash  Co.,  New  York 


1919-22 
1934-39 
1919-39 
1934-39 
1919-31 

1919-37 
1919-31 
1934-37 
1919-39 

1919-22 
1919-21 

1919-24 
1919-21 
1934-37 


1919-39 


1936-39 
1936-39 
1936-39 


1938-39 
1938-39 
1938-39 


1936-39 


1938-39 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR 


213 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Producers  Linter  Export  Co.,  New  Orleans 

Organized  in  1924  to  ship  cotton  linters  for 
account  of  mills  in  Louisiana,  Texas,  Arkan- 
sas, Mississippi,  Georgia,  North  Carolina, 
and  South  Carolina,  the  company  (com- 
mercial copartnership)  operated  for  several 
years,  but  was  affected  by  the  depression, 
and  went  out  of  business  in  1932. 

Members 


Burnett,  Wylie  B.,  Dallas  Tex.. 

Kansas,  Esther,  New  Orleans 

Kohl,  H.  Stephen,  New  Orleans. 
Taylor,  Ralph  F.,  New  Orleans. 


Redwood  Export  Company,  San  Francisco 

Operating  as  an  export  company  before  the 
Webb  law  was  passed,  it  was  one  of  the  first 
to  file  under  the  act  in  1918,  and  has  operated 
successfully  since  that  date,  shipping  red- 
wood to  foreign  countries.  It  reports  as  an 
outstanding  advantage,  ability  to  supply  the 
foreign  markets  promptly  and  satisfactorily 
by  drawing  upon  the  entire  group  of  redwood 
mills  through  a  central  organization  rather 
than  depending  upon  each  unit,  most  of 
which  under  normal  conditions  would  not  be 
able  to  furnish  a  full  cargo  of  export  lumber 
at  one  loading.  The  product  is  standardized, 
inspected  as  to  grade  and  quantity,  and  all 
details  of  sale  and  shipment  are  handled  by 
the  association. 

Members  (class  A)  (stockholders) 

Browne,  J.  H.,  San  Francisco 

Caspar  Lumber  Co.,  San  Francisco 

DeCamp,  C.  E.,  San  Francisco 

Hammond,  A.  B.,  San  Francisco 

Hammond,  L.  C,  San  Francisco 

Hammond  Lumber  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Johnson,  C.  R.,  San  Francisco , 

Murphy,  A.  S.,  San  Francisco 

Nelson,  Chas.,  Co.,  The,  San  Francisco.^ 

Pacific  Lumber  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Tyson,  James,  San  Francisco 

Tyson,  James  (estate),  San  Francisco 

Union  Lumber  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Members  (class  B) 

Dolbeer  &  Carson  Lumber  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Elk  River  Mill  &  Lumber  Co.,  Eureka,  Calf 

Hobbs,  Wall  Lumber  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Holmes  Eureka  Lumber  Co.,  San  Francisco 


Years 


1924 
1927-32 
1924-32 
1925-32 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


19 


1918 

1927-39 

1939 

1918 

1939 

1918-39 

1918,39 

1939 

1918-39 

1918-39 

1918 

1939 

1918-39 


1939 
1939 
1939 
1939 


Period  ol 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1924-32 


1918-39 


214 


CONOENTKATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Redwood  Export  Company — Continued. 

Rockport  Redwood  Co.,  Rockport,  Calif 

Santa  Cruz  Lumber  Co.,  Santa  Cruz,  Calif 

Rice  Export  Association,  New  Orleans,  La 

Formed  in  1937  by  rice  mills  in  Louisiana, 
Texas,  and  Arkansas  (including  several  com- 
panies that  had  held  stock  in  the  Rice  Export 
Corporation,  operating  under  the  act  from 
1929-31,  and  some  that  were  members  of  the 
American  Rice  Export  Corporation  which 
operated  under  the  act  from  1927-33),  the 
association  shipped  rice  to  Cuba  in  1937,  but 
was  affected  by  an  Increase  in  duty  imposed 
by  Cuba  at  the  end  of  1937,  upon  rice  from 
the  United  States,  and  has  not  been  active 


smce. 


Members 


Arkansas  Rice  Growers  Cooperative  Associa- 
tion, De  Witt,  Ark 

Arkansas  Rice  Growers.  Cooperative  Associa- 
tion, Stuttgart,  Ark 

Baton  Rouge  Rice  Mill,  Inc.,  Baton  Rouge, 
La. 


Beaumont  Rice  Mills,  Inc.,  Beaumont,  Tex 

Dore  Rice  Mill,  Crowley,  La 

Edmundson-Duhe  Rice  Mill  Co.,  Inc.,  Rayne, 
La 


El  Campo  Rice  Milling  Co.,  El  Campo,  Tex 

Gulf  Coast  Rice  Mills,  Houston,  Tex 

Imperial  Rice  Milling  Co.,  Crowley,  La 

Jonesboro  Rice  Mill  Co.,  Jonesboro,  Ark 

Kaplan  Rice  Mill,  Inc.,  Kaplan,  La 

Mermentau  Rice  Mill  Co.,  Inc.,  Mermentau, 
La. 


Mouton  Rice  Milling  Co.,  Harrisburg,  Ark 

Noble-Trotter  Rice  Milling  Co.,  Lake  Charles, 
La 


Orange  Rice  Milling  Co.,  Inc.,  Orange,  Tex 

Republic  Rice  Mill,  Inc.,  Gueydan,  La 

Rickert  Rice  Mills,  Inc.,  New  Orleans,  La 

Simon's  Rice  Mill,  Crowley,  La 

Smith  Rice  Mill,  Inc.,  De  Witt,  Ark 

Steinhagen  Rice  Milling  Co.,  Beaumont,  Tex.. 

Tyrrell  Rice  Milling  Co.,  Beaumont,  Tex 

United  Rice  Milling  Products  Co.,  Inc.,  Nev/ 

Orleans,  La 

Walton  Rice  Mill,  Inc.,  Stuttgart,  Ark 


1939 
1939 


Rice  Export  Corporation,  Lake  Charles,  La 

Formed  in  1929  by  rice  millers  in  Louisiana  and 
Texas,  the  association  operated  successfully 
for  about  2  years,  but  in  1931  the  members 
agreed   to  liquidate  and   thereafter  export 


1937-39 

1937-39 

1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 

1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 

1937-39 
1937-39 

1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 
1937-39 

1937-39 
1937-39 


23 


1937-39 


12 


1929-31 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR 


215 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Total  nuiD' 

ber  of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Rice  Export  Corporation — Continued. 

individually.  (5  of  these  companies  joined 
the  Rice  Export  Association  which  was 
formed  under  the  act  in  1937.; 

Members  {stockholders) 

Acadia  Rice  Mills,  Rayne,  La 

Beaumont  Rice  Mills,  Beaumont,  Tex 

El  Campo  Rice  Milling  Co.,  El  Campo,  Tex... 

Galveston  Rice  Milling  Co.,  Galveston,  Tex 

Gulf  Coast  Rice  Milling  Co.,  Houston,  Tex 

Iota  Rice  Milling  Co.,  Iota,  La 

Kaplan  Rice  MiU,  Kaplan,  La .. 

Lake  Charles  Rice  MiUing  Co.,  Lake  Charles, 
La 


Louisiana  State  Rice  MiUing  Co.,  Abbeville,  La. 

Mutual  Rice  Co.  of  Louisiana,  Inc.,  Crowley, 

La _'.. 

Pritchard  Rice  Milling  Co.,  Inc.,  Houston,  Tex. 
Republic  Rice  Mill,  Inc.,  Gueydan,  La 


Rubber  Export  Association,  The,  Akron,  Ohio 

Formed  late  in  1922  by  companies  exporting 
rubber  (including  the  Goodyear  Tire  &  Rub- 
ber Export  Co.,  which  also  files  separately 
under  the  act),  the  a-ssociation  has  operated 
successfully  to  date,  reporting  that  "it  is 
believed  that  this  has  resulted  in  materially 
improving  the  position  of  American  suppliers 
in  their  competition  with  foreign  suppliers 
in  foreign  markets." 

Members 

Firestone  Tire  &  Rubber  Co.,  Akron,  Ohio 

Firestone  Tire  &  Rubber  Export  Co.,  Akron, 

Ohio 

Fisk  Tire  Export  Co.,   Inc.,   Chicopee  Falls, 

Mass 

General  Tire  &  Rubber  Export  Co.,  Akron, 

Ohio 

Goodyear  Tire  &  Rubber  Export  Co.,  Akron, 

Ohio 

International    B.    F.    Goodrich    Corporation, 

Akron,  Ohio 

Kelly  Springfield  Tire  Export  Co.,  Inc.,  New 

York 

Lee  Tire  &  Rubber  Co.  of  New  York,  Inc., 

New  York 

Miller  Rubber  Export  Co.,  Ltd.,  Akron,  Ohio.. 
United  States  Rubber  Export  Co.,  Ltd.,  New 

York 


192^30 
192^31 
1929-31 
1929-31 
1930-31 
1929-31 
1929-31 

1929-31 
1929-31 

1929-31 
1929-31 
1929-31 


1923-28 

1928-39 

1923-33 

1926-39 

1923-39 

1924-39 

1926-33 

1928-32 
1923-30 

1923-39 


10 


1923-39 


2J^6  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 

120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Salmon  Export  Corporation,  Seattle,  Wash 

Formed  in  1926  to  develop  foreign  markets  for 
the  purpose  of  disposing  of  surplus  salmon 
packed  in  the  Northwest,  the  association  did 
some  business  in  1926,  but  in  1927  production 
fell  far  below  normal,  and  thereafter  there 
was  no  surplus  to  ship  abroad.  The  corpo- 
ration became  dissolved  in  1930. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Alaska  Consolidated  Canneries,  Seattle,  Wash. 

Alitak  Packing  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Astoria  &  Puget  Sound  Packing  Co.,   South 

Bellingham ,  Wash 

Carlisle  Packing  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Copper  River  Packing  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Deep  Sea  Salmon  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Emel  Packing  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Hidden  Inlet  Canning  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Kadiak  Fisheries  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Myers,  Geo.  T.,  &  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

North   Pacific  Trading   &   Packing   Co.,   San 

Francisco 

Petersburg  Packing  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Pioneer  Packing  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Pioneer  Sea  Food  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Pyramid  Packing  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Shepard  Point  Packing  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Skinner,  D.  E.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Stuart  Corporation,  Seattle,  Wash 

Sunny  Point  Packing  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash 


Scrap  Export  Associates  of  Americ?,  New  York 

Formed  in  May  1937  to  ship  iron  and  steel 
scrap  to  foreign  countries,  the  association 
was  not  successful  in  negotiating  with  for- 
eign buyers,  and  therefore  in  November  of 
the  same  year  agreed  to  dissolve  and  sell 
individually. 

Members 


Dreifus,  Chas.,  Co.,  Philadelphia 

Joseph,  Robert,  New  York 

Schiavone-Bonomo  Corporation,  New  York 

Shook  Exporters  Association,  Memphis,  Tenn 

Formed  late  in  1931  to  export  wine-barrel 
shooks  to  foreign  markets,  the  association 
has  operated  with  offices  in  New  York, 
Nashville,  Tenn.,  Pekin,  111.,  and  Memphis, 
Tenn.  It  was  at  times  handicapped  by  fail- 
ure of  the  grape  crop  in  Argentina  (an  im- 
portant market)  and  by  depression  conditions 
in   Latin- American   markets;   and   reported 


Years 


1926-29 
1926-30 

1926-30 
1926-30 
1926-30 
1926-30 
1926-30 
1926-30 
1926-30 
1926-30 

1926-29 
1926-30 
1926-30 
1926-30 
1926-30 
1926-30 
1929-30 
1926-30 
1926-30 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


19 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1926-30 


1937 


1932-39 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


217 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 

Total  num- 
ber of 
members 

Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 

Shook  Exporters  Association — Continued. 

that  "it  is  only  by  operating  as  an  associa- 
tion that  we  are  able  to  maintain  prices  in 
face    of    increasing    costs    and    competition 
from  foreign  producers." 

Members 

Brooklyn  Cooperage  Co.,  New  York.- 

1935-39 

1932-39 
1932-38 
1932-39 
1932-36 
1932-39 

1932-38 
1932-39 

2 

8 

Chickasaw    Wood    Products    Co.,    Memphis, 
Tenn                                           _   .   

Export  Cooperage  Co.,  Memphis,  Tenn 

Hamlen,  J.  H.,  &  Son,  Portland,  Maine 

Paducah  Cooperage  Co.,  Paducah,  Ky 

Pekin  Cooperage  Co.,  Pekin,  111  .   __ 

Rocky  River  Coal  &  Lumber  Co.,  Nashville, 
Tenn                                       _          _        

Southport  Corporation,  Inc.,  New  Orleans 

Signal  Export  Association,  New  York 

1931-39 

Formed  to  export  railway   signal  equipment 
and  other  apparatus  to  such  foreign  coun- 
tries as  the  board  of  managers  may  deter- 
mine, some  sales  were  made  to  the  Soviet, 
but  the  association  is  now  inactive. 

Members 

General  Railway  Signal  Co.,  New  York 

Union  Switch  &  Signal  Co.,  Swissville,  Pa 

Southi  American  Fruit  Exporters,  Inc.,  New  York. 

1931-39 
1931-39 

1927-31 

This  association  was  formed  by  New  York  ex- 
port houses,  to  ship  fruit  to  Latin-American 
markets,  and  operated  successfully  for  sev- 
eral years.     It  was  then  affected  by  import 
restrictions    in    Argentina,    which    seriously 
curtailed  the  exportation  of  apples  from  this 
country.     Some  of  the  exporters  in  this  group 
went  out  of  business,  and  others  discontin- 
ued their  fruit  exports.    The  association  was, 
therefore,  dissolved.     During  its  operation  it 
reported  substantial  savings  through  cooper- 
ative action,  especially  through  negotiation 
of  freight  rates. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Diedrichs  &  Co.,  New  York                        

1927-30 
1927-30 
1930-31 
1927-30 
1927-30 
1927-30 
1927-30 
1927-31 

Fernandes,  P.  D  ,  Co  ,  New  York    _          

Holtorf  &  Lindner,  Inc.,  New  York 

Park,  Holtorf  &  Guy,  New  York                

Sorenson  &  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York . 

Steinhardt  &  Kelly,  New  York  ._     

Ultramares  Corporation,  New  York 

Waterman,  Edmund,  &  Co.,  New  Yoi'k 

218 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEB 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Standard  Oil  Export  Corporation,  New  York. 

Formed  in  December  1928  to  ship  petroleum 
and  petroleum  products,  the  association  did 
a  substantial  business  and  reported  advan- 
tages derived  by  central  control  and  coor- 
dination of  export  terms  and  policies. 
Some  of  the  members  imported  crude  oil, 
refined  it,  and  exported  the  refined  products. 
In  1933  and  1934,  however,  the  association 
reported  a  substantial  lessening  of  exports 
due  to  the  fact  that  a  tariff  placed  on  im- 
ports of  crude  oil  (United  States  Revenue 
Act  of  1932)  had  greatly  reduced  importa- 
tion, with  a  consequent  reduction  in  exports. 
Lower  prices  and  keen  competition  of 
foreign  producers  also  lessened  export  sales, 
The  association  was  throughout  its  existence 
a  member  of  the  larger  Webb-law  group. 
Export  Petroleum  Association,  Inc.  Both 
associations  became  dissolved  in  1936. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Carter  Oil  Co.,  The,  Tulsa,  Okla 

Humble  Oil  &  Refining  Co.,  Houston,  Tex 

Lago  Petroleum  Corporation,  New  York 

Standard  Oil  Co.  of  Louisiana,  Baton  Rouge, 
La 

Standard  Oil  Co.  of  New  Jersey,  New  York 

Standard  Oil  Co.  (New  Jersey),  New  York 

Steel   Export   Association  of  America,   The,   New 
York 

Organized  in  1928,  the  association  is  engaged 
in  export  trade  in  steel  products  shipped  to 
foreign  countries.  It  reports  as  chief  ad- 
vantages under  the  act,  ability  to  meet 
foreign  competition  through  establishing 
uniform  terms  and  contracts  for  export  sales, 
standardizing  weights  and  qualities,  and  the 
collection  and  exchange  of  information  re- 
garding foreign  markets. 

Members 

Armco  International  Corporation,  The,  Mid- 
dletown,  Ohio-  _" 

Bethlehem  Steel  Export  Corporation,  New 
York 

Central  Tube  Co.,  Pittsburgh 

Inland  Steel  Co.,  Chicago 

Jones  &  Laughlin  Steel  Co.,  Pittsburgh 

McKeesport  Tin  Plate  Co.,  McKeesport,  Pa.-. 
Newport  RoUing  Mill  Co.,  The,  Newport,  Ky.. 

Pittsburgh  Steel  Co.,  Pittsburgh 

Pittsburgh  Steel  Products  Co.,  Pittsburgh 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1929-36 
1929-35 
1935-36 

1929-36 
1929-36 
1935-36 


1939 

1928-39 

1928-37 

1939 

1928-39 

1928-38 

1939 

1932-39 

1928-32 


17 


1929-36 


1928-39 


eONCENTEATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


219 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Steel  Export  Association  of  America,  The — Con. 
Republic  Iron  &  Steel  Co.,  Youngstown,  Ohio-. 
Republic  Steel  Corporation,  Youngstown  and 

Cleveland,  Ohio 

South  Chester  Tube  Co.,  Chester,  Pa 

Spang,  Chalfarit  &  Co.,  Pittsburgh,  Pa 

United  States  Steel  Products  Co.,  New  York.. 

Weirton  Steel  Co.,  Weirton,  W.  Va 

Wheeling  Steel  Corporation,  Wheeling,  W.  Va.. 
Youngstown  Sheet  &  Tube  Co.,  The,  Youngs- 
town, Ohio ■ 


Sugar  Export  Corporation,  New  York 

Formed  in  1922  to  sell  in  export  sugar  and 
sugar  products,  for  2  large  companies,  the 
association  reported  a  reduction  of  costs 
througfi  centralization  of  the  exports  of 
member  concerns  in  one  common  selling 
agency,  a  saving  in  cable  and  correspondence 
expense  and  economy  in  handling  shipping 
papers  and  banking  details.  One  of  the 
members  withdrew  in  1933;  the  corporation 
has  continued  to  export  for  the  American 
Sugar  Refining  Co.,  and  to  file  papers  with 
the  Commission,  although  it  is  no  longer  a 
combine. 

Members  (stockholders) 

American  Sugar  Refinin,'?  Co.,  The,  New  York. 
National  Sugar  Refining  Co.  of  New  Jersey, 
New  York 


Sulphur  Export  Corporation,  New  York 

The  association  has  been  operating  since  1922, 
selling  crude  sulfur  in  foreign  markets.  It 
reports  success  in  building  up  an  important 
foreign  market  for  American  sulfur.  Ex- 
port terms  of  sale  are  agreed  upon,  and 
economy  is  effected  by  combining  shipments 
and  obtaining  advantageous  freight  rates. 

Members  (stockholders) 


Aldridge,  Walter  H.,  New  York 

Freeport  Sulphur  Co.,  New  York 

Freeport  Texas  Co.,  New  York 

Holmes,  Ralph  C,  New  York 

Judson,  Wilber,  New  York 

Kilbreth,  James  T.,  New  York 

Norton,  Eugene  L.,  New  York 

Snider,  Clarence  A.,  New  York 

Swenson,  Eric  P.,  New  York 

Swenson,  S.  Magnus,  New  York 

Texas  Gulf  Sulphur  Co.,  New  York.. 
Union  Sulphur  Co.,  The.,  New  York. 
Whiton,  Henry,  New  York 


Years 


1928-30 

1930-39 
1928-33 
1928-39 
1928-39 
1928-39 
1928-39 

1928-39 


1922-39 
1922-33 


1922-39 
1937-39 
1922-37 
1930-34 
1922-39 
1928-39 
1930-34 
1922-34 
1922-30 
1922-30 
1922-39 
1922-28 
1922-28 


Total  num 

ber  of 
members 


13 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


1922-39 


1922-39 


220 


CONOENTBATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 

Total  num- 
ber of 
members 

Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 

Textile  Export  Association  of  the  United  States, 
New  York . 

77 

1930-39 

The  association  has  been  in  successful  opera- 
tion since  1930  exporting  textiles;  the  busi- 
ness is  largely  in  cotton  piece  goods,  cotton 
yarns,  cotton  and  rayon  and  all  rayon  piece 
goods.     It  reports  distinct  advantage  to  the 
members   through   agreement   upon   selling 
terms,  standardized  service  charges,  negoti- 
ation of  freight  rates  with  steamship  line 
conferences,  and  exchange  of  market  infor- 
mation    abroad,  especially    concerning   ex- 
change restrictions  in  foreign  countries. 

Members 

Aimone,  A.  F.,  New  York       _   

1937-39 

1939 

1930-32 

1930-36 
1935-37 
1932-39 
1930-39 
1930-39 
1930-39 
1930-39 
1930-36 
1935-36 
1938-39 
1930-39 
1930-35 
1936-39 
1937-39 
1930-37 
1931-38 
1930-33 
1935-37 
1937-39 
1934-35 
1930-33 
1933-39 
1935-39 
1930-32 
1932-39 
1938-39 
1937-39 
1930-31 
1931-34 
1933-39 
1937-39 
1930-32 
1935-39 
1930-32 
1939 

American  Enka  Corporati  n,  New  York 

Amory,  Browne  &  Co.,  N  w  York         

Anderson,  William,  Textil    Manufacturing  Co., 
New  York  __ 

Arnold  Sales  Corporation,  New  York 

Baily,  Joshua  L.,  &  Co.,  New  York      

Barrell,  WiUiam  L.,  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Bear  Mill  Manufacturing  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York. 
Beir,  Arthur,  &  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Berliner,  Edwin  E.,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Bernheimer,  Jacob  S.,  &  Bro.,  New  York 

Bernstein,  Harold,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Bliss,  Fabyan  &  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York.         

Borden,  M.  C.  D.,  &  Sons,  Inc.,  New  York 

Brand  &  Oppenheimer,  Inc.,  New  York 

Brune,  Nadler  &  Cuffe,  New  York   __    _. 

Brune,  Pottberg  &  Co.,  New  York 

Callaway  Mills,  Inc.,  New  York 

Cannon  Mills,  Inc.,  New  York..   .   

Carnac  Cottons,  Inc.,  New  York .- 

Casas  &  Co.,  New  York                  .   .   

Castillo,  Rafael  del,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Cohn-Hall-Marx  Co.,  New  York               .   _   . 

Cone  Export  &  Commission  Co.,  New  York 

Consolidated  SeUing  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Crystal  Springs  Bleachery,  Inc.,  New  York 

du  Pont,  E.  I.,  de  Nemours  &  Co.,  New  York_- 
Epstein,  Leo  J.,  New  York   .     _         

Erwin  Yarn  Agency,  Inc.,  Philadelphia — 

Erwin  Yarn  Co.,  Inc.,  Philadelphia __ 

Federated  Textiles,  Inc.,  New  York 

Fine  Goods  Sales  Associates,  Inc.,  New  York__ 
Fluegelman,  N.,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Franklin  Manufacturing  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York.. 

Garner  &  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Getz  Bros.,  New  York 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


221 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Textile  Export  Association  of  the  United  States — 
Continued. 

Glass,  Henry,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Griffin,  Charles  E.,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Hall,  Louis  F.,  &  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Haywood,    Mackay   &   Valentine,    Inc.,    New 

York.. 

Haywood- Mackay  Department,  Bliss,  Fabyan 

&  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York , 

Heaney,  Everett,  &  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York^ 

Heymann  Mercantile  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Hinck,  Otto  H.,  New  York 

Iselin-Jeflferson  Co.,  New  York 


Johnson  Arthur  R.,  Co.,  New  York 

Julliard,  A.  D.,  &  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Lamport  Manufacturers  Supply  Co.,  Inc.,  The, 
New  York . 

Leveen,  E.  F.,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Lowenstein,  M.,  &  Sons,  Inc.,  New  York 


McKay,  W.  E.,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Manufacturers  Textile  Export  Co.,  Inc.,  New 
York 

Minot,  Hooper  &  Co.,  New  York 

Mosheim,  E.,  &  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York.. 

Munoz  &  Co.,  New  York 

Nashua  Manufacturing  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York... 

Neuss,  Hesslein  &  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Noveltex,  Inc.,  New  York 

Pacific  Mills,  New  York 

Paulson,  Linkroum  &  Co.,  New  York 

Pepperell  Manufacturing  Co.,  New  York 

Pollack,  Max,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Prince,  Lauten  Corporation,  New  York 

Princely  Mills  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Simpson,  William,  Sons  &  Co.,  New  York 

Smith,  Kirkpatrick  &  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Southeastern  Cottons,  Inc.,  New  York 

Stafford,  G.  A.,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Stettauer  Harris  &  Raphael,  New  York.: 

Stevens,  J.  P.,  &  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Taylor,  Clapp  &  Beall,  New  York .. 

Til  ton  &  Keeler,  Inc.,  New  York 

Trippe,  Barker  &  Co.,  New  York 

Turner,  Halsey  Co.,  New  York 

United    Merchants   &    Manufacturers   Export 

Co.,  New  York 

Wellington,  Sears  &  Co.,  New  York 

Woodward,  Baldwin  &  Co.,  New  York 

Textile  Manufacturers  Alliance,  Inc.,  New  York  — 
This  association  was  formed  in  1919  as  the  Tex- 
tile Alliance  Export  Corporation,  changing 
its  name  in  the  same  year  to  the  title  listed 
above.     Its  purpose  was  to  export  cotton 


1930-39 
1930-32 
1930-32 

1935-36 

1937-38 
1932-34 
1933-39 
1930-39 
1930-33 
1938-39 
1937-39 
1935-39 

1930-39 
1930-33 
1930-32 
1935-39 
1935-39 

1931-39 
1930-39 
1930-37 
1933-39 
1930-39 
1930-39 
1930-31 
1930-39 
1930-32 
1930-31 
1935-39 
1930-39 
1932-35 
1937-39 
1930-36 
1934r-39 
1930-39 
1930r31 
1930-31 
1930-32 
1930-32 
1931-36 
1930-39 

19^30-32 
1930-31 
1930-39 


Period  0/ 
assod- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


36 


1919-20 


222 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEE 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 

Total  num- 
ber of 
members 

Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 

Textile  Manufacturers  Alliance,  Inc. — Continued, 
and  woolen  fabrics,  yarns,  hosier}',  under- 
wear, and  blankets.     It  operated  at  first  as 
agent  for  the  members,  then  reorganized  to 
purchase  the  goods  from  the  producers  and 
resell  them  abroad.     It  wished,  however,  to 
ship  to  the  Philippines,  and  also  to  import 
products  received  in  exchange  for  exports; 
since  these  were  not  export  functions  within 
the  terms  of  the  law,  the  association  with- 
drew from  operation  under  the  act. 

Members  {^stockholders) 

Aliierican  Association  of  Woolen  and  Worsted 
Manufacturers,  New  York          .   

1919 
1919-20 

1919 

1919-20 

191&-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919 

1919-20 

1919^20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

191^20 

1919 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919 

1919-20 

1919-20 

1919-20 

American  Woolen  Products  Co.,  New  York 

Association   Cotton  Textile   Merchants,   New 
York.. 

Baily,  Joshua  L.,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Baldwin,  William  H.,  New  York 

Bates,  W.  C„  New  York             __. 

Bliss,  Fabyan  &  Co.,  New  York . 

Borden,  M.  C.  D.,  &  Sons,  New  York 

Cannon  Mills,  New  York 

Catlin  &  Co.,  New  York 

Cone  Export  &  Commission  Co.,  New  York 

Converse  &  Co.,  New  York  _. 

Deering,  Milliken  &  Co.,  New  York 

Duval,  W.  H.,  &  Co.,  New  York.. 

Howe,  Henry  W.,  New  York 

Iselin,  Wm.,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Kunhardt,  Geo.  E.,  Corporation,  New  York 

Lawrence,  John  S. ,  Boston     

McKenney,  H.  P.,  &  Co.,  New  York 

Metcalf,  Manton  B.,  New  York 

Munn,  John  R.,  New  York 

National  Association  of  Wool  Manufacturers, 
Boston 

National  Council  of  American  Cotton  Manu- 
facturers, Charlotte,  N.  C               

Nichols,  Geo.,  New  York 

Parker,  Wilder  &  Co.,  New  York 

Poor,  J.  Harper,  New  York 

Rupprecht,  Frederick  K.,  New  York 

Smith,  Hogg  &  Co.,  New  York 

Stevens,  J.  P.,  &  Co.,  New  York       

Taubel,  Wm.  F.,  Inc.,  New  York     

Turner,  J.  Spencer,  Co.,  New  York 

Turner,  Halsey  Co.,  New  York 

Watta,  Ridley,  New  York               

Watts,  Stebbins  &  Co  ,  New  York            

Whitman,  Wm.,  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Wood,  Geo.,  Sons  &  Co.,  Philadelpia 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWKDR  223 

320  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  nam 

ber  of 
members 


Period  of 
assocl- 
atiOQ 
opera- 
tion 


United  Export  Lumber  Association,  Seattle,  Wash.. 
Formed  in  1931  to  include  the  Douglas  Fir 
Exploitation  &  Export  Co.  (operating  as  an 
export  association  under  the  act)  and  other 
export  firms,  representing  86  mills  in  the 
Northwest,  the  association  was  not  a  success 
and  became  dissolved  in  1932. 

Members 

Dant  &  Russell  Export  Co.,  Portland,  Greg. 
(representing  2  mills) 

Douglas  Fir  Exploitation  &  Export  Co.,  Seattle, 
Wash,  (representing  78  miUs) 

Grays  Harbor  Exportation  Co.,  Aberdeen, 
Wash,  (representing  6  mills) ^. 


1931-32 


1931-32 
1931-32 
1931-32 


United  Paint  &  Varnish  Export  Co.,  The,  Cleve- 
land, Ohio 

Formed  in  Decernber  1919  to  sell  the  products 
of  the  Sherwin-Williams  Co.  and  its  sub- 
sidiaries in  foreign  markets,  the  association 
reported  economy  eflfected  through  con- 
solidation of  packing,  billing,  and  handling 
of  the  goods,  and  duplication  of  effort  abroad, 
1  representative  hajidling  the  several  lines, 
until  1926  when  it  reported  that  sales  were 
being  handled  individually  by  the  member 
companies;  and  in  1929  the  association  was 
dissolved. 

Members  {stockholders) 

Cottingham,  W.  H.,  Cleveland 

Douglas,  H.  J.,  Cleveland _ 

Fenn,  S.  P.,  Cleveland 

Gemberling,  H.  L.,  Newark,  N.  J__ 

Levenhagen,  R.  W.,  Cleveland 

Martin,  George  A.,  Cleveland , 

Schroeder,  L.  H.,  Cleveland 

Sherwin-Williams  Co.,  The,  Cleveland 

Whittlesey,  H.  D.,  Cleveland .._ 

United  States  Alkali  Export  Association,  New  York. 
Formed  in  1919  to  export  caustic  soda  and 
soda  ash,  bicarbgnate  of  soda,  and  allied 
products  (miscellaneous  quantities  of  cal- 
cium chloride,  sodium  chloride,  liquid 
chlorine,  and  modified  sodas)  this  associa- 
tion has  operated  successfully  to  date.  It 
reports  economy  effected  in  seUing  cost  at 
home  and  abroad,  through  establishment  of 
a  central  bureau  to  handle  export  sales. 
This  agency  can  secure  definite  and  compre- 
hensive information  from  a  wide  variety  of 


1920-23 

1927-29 

1920-27 

1920-29 

1920 

1920-29 

1923-29 

1920-29 

1920-29 


1920-29 


17 


1919-39 


224 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Total  num- 
ber of 
memtera 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


United  States  Alkali  Export  Association — Con. 

sources,  relative  to  the  status  of  foreign 
markets,  in  the  matter  of  prices,  shipping 
facilities,  consular  regulations,  stocks  on 
hand,  and  the  credit  situation.  A  compre- 
hensive study  of  certain  foreign  markets  has 
been  possible,  and  competition  from  abroad 
has  been  met  through  the  efforts  of  the  as- 
sociation more  satisfactorily  than  if  business 
had  been  secured  individually  by  the  mem- 
bers. In  summary,  the  assoeiifttion  reports 
that  "we  have  become  more  convinced  of  the 
necessity  for  united  effort  in  matters  of  for- 
eign trade  due  to  the  experience  and  knowl- 
,edge  we  have  gained  since  operating  under 
.the  Webb  law."  The  association  cooperates 
with  the  California  Alkali  Export  Associa- 
tion, formed  under  the  Webb  law  in  1936. 

Members  (stockholders) 


Church  &  D wight  Co.,  Inc.,  New  York 

Columbia  Chemical  Co.,  Cincinnati 

Columbia    Development    Corporation,    Pitts- 
burgh  

Diamond  Alkali  Co.,  Pittsburgh 

Dow  Chemical  Co.,  Midland,  Mich 

Hooker  Electrochemical  Co.,  New  York 

Mathieson  Alkali  Works,  Inc.,  New  York 

Michigan  Alkali  Co.,  Detroit 

Niagara  Alkali  Co.,  New  York 

Pennsylvania  Salt  Manufacturing  Co.,  Phila- 
delphia  

Pittsburgh  Plate  Glass  Co.,  Pittsburgh 

Republic  Chemical  Co.,  Pittsburgh 

Solvay  Process  Co.,  Syracuse,  N.  Y 

Southern  Alkali  Corporation,  Pittsburgh 

Vulcan  Detinning  Co.,  Sewaren,  N.  J 

Wamer-Klipstein  Chemical  Co.,  New  York 

Westvaco  Chlorine  Products,  Inc.,  New  York. 

United  States  Button  Export  Co.,  Muscatine,  Iowa. 
Formed  in  1921  to  export  the  products  of  the 
United  States  Button  Co.,  and  to  cooperate 
in  export  policies  with  other  button  ex- 
porters, through  the  Webb  law  group. 
Associated  Button  Exporters  of  America, 
Inc.,  the  association  found  it  impossible  to 
compete  in  the  European  market  with 
Czechoslovakian  producers.  It  did  some 
business  in  Latin-American  countries,  but 
there  met  with  severe  competition  from 
Japanese  buttons.  It  finally  became  dis- 
solved in  1928. 


1930-39 
1919-20 

1935-39 
1919-39 
1934-39 
1919-39 
1919-39 
1919-39 
1934-39 

1919-39 
1920-35 
191^20 
1919-39 
1935-39 
1920-21 
1919-22 
1922-39 


1921-28 


I 


(CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR 


225 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  o  1 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


United  States  Button  Export  Co — Continued. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Adams,  A.  C,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

Hagermann,  Edw.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

Steinmetz,  Paul,  Muscatine,  Iowa 

United  States  Button  Co.,  Muscatine,  Iowa... 

United  States  Forest  Products  Co.,  Kansas  City, 
Mo 


1922-23 
1922-23 
1922-23 
1921-28 


Formed  in  1919  to  export  yellow  pine  lumber 
and  wood  products  generally,  the  associa- 
tion never  came  into  operation,  and  was 
finally  dissolved. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Bonner,  B.  F.,  Kirby  Lumber  Co.,  Houston, 
Tex 

Burgoyne,  C.  R.,  Bagdad  Land  &  Lumber  Co., 

Pensacola,  Fla 

Carney,  W.  M.,  Mill  Co.,  Atmore,  Ala 

Clark,  A.  L.,  Standard  Lumber  Co.,  Dallas, 

Tex 

Hallowell,    R.    M.,    Industrial    Lumber    Co., 

Elizabeth,  La 

Joyce,  A.  G.,  Tremont  Lumber  Co.,  Chicago. - 
Joyce,  James  S.,  Trinity  County  Lumber  Co., 

Groveton,  Tex 

Keith,  Charles  S.,  Delta  Land  &  Timber  Co., 

Kansas  City,  Mo 

McLane,  J.  R.,  Alabama  &  Florida  Lumber 

Co.,  Noma,  Fla 

Peavy,    A.    J.,    Peavy-Byrnes    Lumber    Co., 

Shreveport,  La 

Rosasco,  Peter,  Bay  Point  Mill  Co.,  Pensa- 
cola, Fla 

Wiener,   Eli,   Angelina   County   Lumber   Co., 

Keltys,  Tex 

Wier,  R.  W.,  Long  Leaf  Lumber  Co.,  Houston, 

Tex. 

United  States  Handle  Export  Co.,  The  Piqua,  Ohio_ . 
Formed  in  1919  to  export  wooden  handles  for 
tools,  shovels,  brooms,  etc.,  also  churns, 
woodenware,  and  hardwood  flooring,  the 
association  operated  successfully  for  several 
years,  reporting  economy  through  coopera- 
tive selling,  elimination  of  separate  export 
departments,  distribution  of  orders  among 
the  members,  standardization  of  grades,  and 
saving  in  freight  rates  through  consolidation 
of  shipments.  During  the  depression  it  re- 
ported difficulty  in  selling  at  profitable  prices, 
due  to  reduced  purchasing  power  in  foreign 


1919-22 

1919-22 
1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 
1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-22 


13 


191^22 


15 


1919-39 


226 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EC50N0MIC  POWEH 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


United  States  Handle  Export  Co. — Continued. 

markets:  "This  is  particularly  true,  since  our 
goods  are  used  principally  in  agricultural 
areas  and  the  prices  of  agricultural  products 
are  very  low."  In  1932  the  association 
oflices  were  closed  "due  to  depressed  condi- 
tions and  state  of  trade  in  foreign  countries." 
Reports  were  filed  with  the  Commission  un- 
til 1939  in  the  hope  that  conditions  would 
improve,  but  the  name  has  now  been  re- 
moved from  the  Commission's  list. 

Members  (stockholders) 


Barnett,  C.  H.,  Piqua,  Ohio 

Bassett,  H.  Lee,  Cleveland,  Ohio 

Bassett,  Herbert  W.,  and  estate  of  Herbert  W. 

Bassett,  Columbus,  Ind 

Bassett,   Myra   W.,   and  estate  of   Myra   W. 

Bassett,  Columbus,  Ind 

Bassett,  William  F.,  Columbus,  Ind 

Crook,  Son  &  Co.,  Hicksville,  Ohio 

DurreJl,  George  B.,  Cleveland,  Ohio 

Ferguson,  A.  W.,  Willoughby,  Ohio 

Flesh,  L.  M.,  Piqua,  Ohio 

LaFontaine  Handle  Co.,  Decatur,  Ind 

Leonard,  A.  M.,  Piqua,  Ohio 

May,  J.  E.,  Columbus,  Ind 

Rogers,  William  Cook,  Piqua,  Ohio 

Ross,  C.  A.,  Piqua,  Ohio 

Way,  C.  S.,  Columbus,  Ind 


United  States  Maize  Products  Export  Association, 

Inc.,  New  York  City  and  WiJkes-Barre,  Pa 

Organized  in  1919  as  the  American  Maize 
Products  Export  Association,  an  unincor- 
porated group,  the  association  was  incorpo- 
rated in  1920,  and  the  name  was  changed  to 
United  States  Maize.  Its  purpose  was  to 
export  "products  of  degerminated  Indian 
corn  or  maize"  as  agent  for  the  member 
mills.  Some  shipments  were  made,  but  the 
association  was  unable  to  develop  a  foreign 
market,  reporting  in  1924  that  "there  has 
been  no  demand  for  corn  products,  and  we 
are  merely  holding  the  corporation  intact  in 
hopes  there  may  be  a  favorable  change  and  a 
chance  to  transact  business."  It  was 
finally  dissolved  in  1926. 

Members  (stockholders) 

Adams,  W.  N.,  Arkadelphia,  Ark... 

American  Hominy  Co.,  Indianapolis 

Arkadelphia  Mill  Co.,  Arkadelphia,  Ark. 


1919-39 
1919-39 

1919-29 

1919-23 
1919-39 
1928-39 
1927-39 
1927-39 
1919-20 
1927-39 
1919-24 
1920-23 
1919-39 
1924-39 
1920-23 


1922-25 
1919-22 

; 192 I -22 

11926 


18 


1919-26 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEK 


227 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num 

ber  of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
at}on 
opera- 
tion 


United  States  Maize  Products  Export  Association- 
Continued. 

Aunt  Jemima  Mill  Co.,  St.  Joseph,  Mo 

Ballard  &  Ballard  Co.,  Louisville,  Ky 

Chivington,  T.  M.,  Chicago 

Clark,  Rob't  R.,  St.  Joseph,  Mo 

International  Milling  Co.,  New  Prague,  Minn. 

Kroupe,  Chas.  A.,  Mill  Co.,  Milwaukee 

Lafayette  Corn  Flour  Mills,  Lafayette,  Ind._. 

Licht,  Louis  J.,  Geneva,  N.  Y 

Louisville  Cereal  Mill  Co.,  Louisville,  Ky 

Miner,  Asher,  Wilkes-Barre,  Pa 

Miner,  Rob't  C,  Wilkes-Bari^,  Pa 


Miner-Hillard  Milling  Co.,  Wilkes-Barre,  Pa... 
Patent  Cereals  Co.,  Geneva,  N.  Y 


Standard  Cereal  Co.,  Chillicothe,  Ohio. 
Wathen  Mill  Co.,  Louisville,  Ky 


/1921-22 

11926 
1919-22 
1922-25 
1922-25 
1920-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1922-25 
191^22 
1922-25 
1922-25 

/ 1919-22 

11926 

/1919-22 

11926 
1919-22 
1919-22 


United  States  Office  Equipment  Export  Association, 
New  York.  _ _ 

Organized  for  the  purpose  of  exporting  office 
desks,  filing  cabinets,  bookcases,  and  other 
office  equipment  the  association  reported  that 
"the  fact  that  one  concern  is  able  to  supply 
everything  necessary  for  the  equipinent  of  a 
modern  office  is  an  advantage  in  the  handling 
of  foreign  sales."  The  New  York  office  of 
the  association  was  said  to  be  of  great  con- 
venience to  factories  located  inland.  In 
1923,  however,  the  members  voted  to  sell 
separately,  and  the  association  was  dis- 
solved. 

Members 

Commercial  Furniture  Co.,  Chicago 

Globe- Wernicke  Co.,  The,  Cincinnati 

Marble,  B.  L.,  Chair  Co.,  The,  Bedford,  Ohio... 

United  States  Provision  Export  Corporation,  Chi- 
cago. . 

Formed  in  1919  to  export  food  productsj  prin- 
cipally packing-house,  agricultural,  and 
dairy  products,  the  association  operated 
until  1922,  but  reported  obstacles  in  develop- 
ing business  abroad,  such  as  financial  difficul- 
ties of  buyers,  dropping  markets,  and  losses 
due  to  cancelation  of  contracts.  It  there- 
fore went  out  of  business. 

Members  {stockholders) 

Arnold  Bros.,  Chicago 

Blumenstock  &  Reid,  Cleveland 

Burkhardt,  Henry,  Packing  Co.,  Dayton,  Ohio.. 

257769— 41— No.  6 16 


1918-23 
1918-23 
1918-23 


1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22  I 


1918-23 


21 


1919-22 


228 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Yews 

Total  num- 
ber of 
members 

Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
.tion 

United    States    Provision    Export    Corporation — 
Continued. 

Columbus  Packing  Co.,  Columbus,  Ohio 

Drovers  Packing  Co.,  Kansas  City,  Kans 

Dyer,  W.  H.,  Packing  Co.,  Evansville,  Ind 

East  Side  Packing  Co.,  East  St.  Louis,  111 

Evansville  Packing  Co.,  Evansville,  Ind 

Focke,  Wm.,  Sons  Co.,  Dayton,  Ohio 

Home  Packing  &  Ice  Co.,  Terre  Haute,  Ind 

Interstate  Packing  Co.,  Winona,  Minn 

1919-22 
1919-22 
191^22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22^ 
1919-22 
-  1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1919-22 
1^19 

Lake  Erie  Provision  Co-,  Cleveland,  Ohio 

Louisville  Provision  Co.,  Louisville,  Ky 

Mayer,  Oscar  F.,  &  Bro.,  Chicago 

Nuckolls  Packing  Co. ,  Puebro,  C  olo 

Ogden  Packing  &  Provision  Co.,  Ogden,  Utah___ 
Ohio  Provision  Co.,  Cleveland,  Ohio     

Powers,  Begg  &  Co.,  Jacksonville,  111 

Rath  Packing  Co. ,  Waterloo,  Iowa 

Ruddy,  Thos.,  Co.,  Kansas  City,  Kans 

Sucher,  Chas.,  Packing  Co.,  Dayton,  Ohio 

Theurer  Norton  Provision  Co.,  Cleveland,  Ohio. 
Wilson  Provision  Co.,  Peoria,  111               

WolfiF,  Chas.,  Packing  Co.,  Topeka,  Kans-_ 

Walnut  Export  Sales  Co.,  Inc.,  Kansas  City,  Kans. 

19 

191^3 

(formerly  in  Chicago,  111.). 

Formed  in  1919  to  export  walnut  and  walnut 
products  (also  Indiana  white^  oak  logs),  the 
association  has  operated  successfully  to  date, 
reporting  that  "by  combining  the  resources 
of  stocks,  experience,  etc.,  of  several  mills, 
we  at  one  time  reduce  the  costs  of  exporting 
as  compared  to  individual  operation,  increase 
the  ability  to  supply  practically  all  items  in 
our  line,  enjoy  the  effects  of  greater  prestige 
in   the  foreign  markets,   and   control  in   a 
greater  measure  the  standards  of  measure- 
ment and  quality." 

Members  (stockholders) 

Amos  Lumber  Co.,  Edinburg,  Ind 

1928-29 
1929-39 
1928-32 
1919-22 

1919 

191&-28 

1919-28 

1919-22 

1919-22 

1919-23 

1919-35 

1928-39 

1922-32 

Amos-Thompson  Co.,  Edinburg,  Ind 

Barnaby,  Chas.  H.,  Greencastle,  Ind 

Central  Timber  Export  Co.,  New  York . 

Chillicothe  Gunstock  Manufacturing  Co.,  Chil- 
licothe,  Ohio__       .                            .-. 

Des  Moines  Sawmill  Co.,  Des  Moines,  Iowa 

Hartzell,  Geo.  W.,  Piqua,  Ohio 

Hoffman  Bros.  Co.,  Fort  Wayne,  Ind 

Hodsier  Veneer  Co.,  Indianapolis,  Ind 

Langton  Lumber  Co.,  Pekin,  111 

Long  Knight  Lumber  Co.,  Indianapolis,  Ind.. 
Maley  &  Wertz  Lumber  Co.,  Evansville,  Ind_. 
Mowbray  &   Robinson  Lumber  Co.,   Cincin- 
nati, Ohio 1 

i 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR 


229 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Walnut  Export  Sales  Co.,  Inc. — Continued. 

Penrod  Walnut  &  Veneer  Co.,  Kansas  City, 
Mo 

Pickrel  Walnut  Co.,  St.  Louis,  Mo 

Pierson  HoUowell  Lumber  Co.,  Indianapolis 

PurceU,  Frank,  Walnut  Lumber  Co.,  Kansas 
City,  Kans 

Ransom,  John  B.,  &  Co.,  Nashville,  Tenn 

Wood-Mosaic  Co.,  Inc.,  Louisville,  Ky 


Walworth  International  Co.,  New  York  (formerly 

in  Boston,  Mass.) 

FoTjned  in  1920  to  act  as  selling  agent  for  the 
Walworth  (Manufacturing)  Co.  and  several 
other  producers  of  pipe  fittings  and  valves,  the 
association  has  operated  successfully  to  date, 
reporting  that  "the  success  of  the  Walworth 
International  Co.  as  a  Webb-Pomerene  or- 
ganization, we  believe,  is  due  chiefly  (if  not 
wholly)  to  the  fact  that  we  have  gone  into 
the  business  of  foreign  trade  in  what  v/e  feel 
is  an  intelligent  manner  and  have  followed  a 
consistent  policy  year  in  and  year  out,  in 
good  times  and  in  poor  times,  of  maintaining 
a  foreign  field  organization.  Through  such 
organization  we  have  been  enabled  to  build 
up  and  maintain  a  recognition  of  the  quality 
of  our  brand.  This  quality  reputation,  to- 
gether with  goodwill  created  by  the  main- 
tenance of  a  continued  foreign  sales  force, 
has  enabled  us  to  continue  to  secure  business 
even  in  the  face  of  European  and  Japanese 
price  competition  of  a  very  serious  type." 

The  company  is  a  member  of  the  Pipe 
Fittings  and  Valve  Export  Association,  al^o 
filing  papers  under  the  act. 

All  stock  has  been  held  by  the  Walworth 
Manufacturing  Co..  now  called  the  Wal- 
worth Co.,  of  Boston  and  New  York. 

Western  Plywood  Export  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Formed  in  1927  to  export  veneers,  plywood, 
and  plywood  products  to  foreign  countries, 
the  association  reported  better  service  to 
buyers,  lower  selling  cost  to  the  individual 
mills,  and  the  opportunity^  to  distribute 
specifications  to  individual  member  mills 
which  best  fit  their  operation.  The  asso- 
ciation undertook  exploitation  work  at  a  low 
cost,  which  was  not  possible  for  the  individ- 
ual mills.  In  1935  another  plywood  export 
association  was  formed,  and  members  of  the 
western  plywood  group  decided  to  dissolve 
the  first  and  join  the  second.  (See  Pacific 
Fofest  Industries.) 


1919-28 
1919-28 
1928-39 

1919-39 
1919-22 
1923-28 


1920-39 


27 


1926-36 


230 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNi:)ER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Western  Plywood  Export  Co. — Continued. 

Members    (stockholders) 

Aircraft  Plywood  Corporation,  Seattle,  Wash. 

Autzen,  Thomas,  Portland,  Greg 

Bailey,  Wm.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Bartells,  G.  L.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Buffelen     Lumber     &     Manufacturing     Co., 

Tacoma,  Wash 

Calloway,  E.  J.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Elliott  Bay  Mill  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash '.... 

Garland,  Philip  (trustee),  Tacoma,  Wash 

Harbor  Plywood  Co.,  Hoquiam,  Wash 

Mackall-Paine  Veneer  Co.,  Vancouver,  Wash. 

Nicolai,  H.  T.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Oregon- Washington    Plywood    Co.,    Tacoma, 

Wash 

Osgood,  Geo.  J.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Peterman  Manufacturing  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash.. 

Peterman,  T.  A.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Portland  Manufacturing  Co.,  Portland,  Oreg_-. 

Robinson,  Jack,  Everett>  Wash 

Robinson  Manufacturing  Co.,  Everett,  Wash.. 

Simpson,  Phillip,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Spencer,  C.  L.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Tacoma  Veneer  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Treasury  of  the  Corporation   (stock  held  by 

Philip     Garland,     trustee,     transferred     to 

Treasury  of  the  Corporation  in  1929) 

Walton,  E.  Q.,  Everett,  Wash 

Walton  Veneer  Co.,  Everett,  Wash 

Washington  Veneer  Co.,  Olympia,  Wash 

Westman,  E.  E.,  Olympia,  Wash 

Wheeler     Osgood     Sales     Corporation,     The, 

Tacoma,  Wash 


Wisconsin  Canners  Export  Association,  Manitowoc, 
Wis 

Formed  in  1919  by  Wisconsin  canners  for  the 
purpose  of  selling  canned  vegetables  (es- 
pecially peas)  under  a  common  label,  in  for- 
eign markets,  the  association  was  not  suc- 
cessful in  developing  an  export  business.  It 
filed  papers  for  several  years  in  the  hope  that 
business  might  be  obtained  but  finally  be- 
came dissolved  in  1929. 

Members 

Adell  Canning  Co.,  Adell,  Wis 

Antigo  Canning  Co.,  Antigo,  Wis ^ 

Badger  Canning  Co.,  Beaver  Dam,  Wis 

■  Beaver  Canning  Co.,  Beaver  Dam,  Wis.- 

Cambria  Canning  Co.,  Cambria,  Wis 

Cedarburg  Canning  Co.,  Cedarburg,  Wis 

Chilton  Canning  Co.,  Chilton,  Wis 


1930-33 
1929-31 
1932-33 
1929-30 

1927-36 
1931-36 
1927-36 
1929-31 
1927-29 
1927-30 
1931-36 

1930-36 
1929-31 
1931-36 
1931-36 
1927-30 
1929-30 
1928-30 
1929-36 
1930-36 
1927-30 


1929-36 
1929-36 
1927-30 
1927-36 
1929-36 

1927-36 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


36 


1920-29 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEB. 


231 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Wisconsin  Canners  Export  Association — Con. 

Dutch  Canning  &  Pickling  Co.,  Cedar  Grove, 
Wis.: 

Fairwater  Canning  Co.,  Markesan,  Wis 

Fort  Atkinson  Canning  Co.,  Fort  Atkinson, 
Wis 

Fox  Lake  Canning  Co.,  Fox  Lake,  Wis 

Fuhreman  Canning  Co.,  De  Forest,  Wis 

Hartford  Canning  Co.,  Hartford,  Wis 

Herfort,  Frank,  Canning  Co.,  Baraboo,  Wis 

Holmen  Canning  Co.,  Holmen,  Wis 

Iron  Ridge  Canning  Co.,  Iron  Ridge,  Wis 

Krier  Preserving  Co.,  Belgium,  Wis 

Lake  Shore  Canning  Co.,  Sheboygan,  Wis 

Lakeside  Packing  Co.,  Manitowoc,  Wis 

Markesan  Canning  Co.,  Markesan,  Wis 

Mayville  Canning  Co.,  Mayville,  Wis 

Milwaukee    River   Canning   Co.,    Thiensville, 

Wis 

New   Holstein    Canning    Co.,    New    Holstein, 

Wis 

Onalaska  Canning  Co.,  Onalaska,  Wis 

Oostburg  Canning  Co.,  Oostburg,  Wis 

Owen  Canning  Co.,  Qwen,  Wis 

Prairie  View  Canning  Co.,  Randolph,  Wis 

Randolph  Canning  Co.,  Randolph,  Wis 

Rockfield  Canning  Co.,  Rockfield,  Wis 

Sauk  City  Canning  Co.,  Sauk  City,  Wis 

Sun  Prairie  Canning  Co.,  Sun  Prairie,  Wis 

Watertown  Canning  Co.,  Watertown,  Wis 

Waupun  Canning  Co.,  Waupun,  Wis 

West  Bend  Canning  Co.,  West  Bend,  Wis 

West  Salem  Canning  Co.,  West  Salem,  Wis 

Wisconsin  Pea  Canners  Co.,  Manitowoc,  Wis.. 

Wood  Naval  Stores  Export  Association,  Wilming- 
ton,  Del 

Formed  in  1935  to  export  wood  naval  stores 
(rosin  an)d  pine  oil  produced  by  wood  distil- 
lation) through  the  export  offices  of  the  Her- 
cules Powder  Co.,  the  association  operated 
successfully  until  1938,  when  another  export 
association  was  formed  to  ship  the  same  prod- 
ucts, and  some  of  the  members  of  the  first 
group  joined  the  second.  (See  International 
Wood  Naval  Stores  Export  Association.) 
The  first  group  was,  therefore,  dissolved.  It 
was  reported  that  operation  of  the  associa- 
tion "contributed  a  great  deal  to  the  orderly 
marketing  of  pine  oil  and  F.  F.  wOod  rosin 
in  the  export  channels." 

Members 

Continental  Turpentine  &  Rosin  Corporation, 
Laurel,  Miss - 


1920-29 
1920-29 

1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-24 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1923-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 

1920-29 

1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-29 
1920-23 


1935-38 


1936-37 


232 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Years 


Total  num- 
ber of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
opera- 
tion 


Wood  Naval  Stores  Export  Association — Con. 

Dixie  Pine  Products  Co.,  Hattiesburg,  Miss 

Hercules  Powder  Co.,  Wilmington,  Del, 

Mackie  Pine  Products  Co.,  Covington,  La 

Phoenix  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Gulfport,  Miss 


1935-38 
1935-38 
1935-38 
1935-38 


Wood  Pipe  Export  Co  ,  Seattle,  Wash 

Formed  in  1920  to  export  wood  pipe,  wood 
tanks  and  silos,  and  accessories,  to  foreign 
countries,  the  association  did  some  business 
in  South  America  but  was  unable  to  develop 
enough^  trade  to  warrant  continuing  the  or- 
ganization. It  therefore  became  dissolved 
in  1923. 

Members  {stockholders) 

American  Wood  Pipe  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Continental  Pipe  Manufacturing  Co.,  Seattle.. 

Garrison,  T.  B.  (trustee),  Seattle 

Gerken,  G.  T.,  San  Francisco 

Insinger,  F.  N.,  Tacoma,  Wash 

Long,  Joe  L.  (trustee) ,  Seattle 

Morrill,  Vaughan  (trustee),  Tacoma,  Wash 

Munroe,  H.  K.,  Seattle,  Wash 

Pacific  Tank  &  Pipe  Co.,  San  Francisco 

Pitcher,  E.  C.  (trustee),  San  Francisco 

Redwood  Manufacturers  Co.,  San  Friincisco 

Wood,  C.  J.  (trustee),  San  Francisco 

Worden,  H.  B.,  San  Francisco 


1920-23 

1920-23 

1920 

1920-23 

1920-23 

1920-23 

1920-23 

1920-23 

1920-23 

1920-23 

1920-23 

1920-23 

1920-23 


Zinc  Export  Association,  Inc.,  New  York 

Formed  in  1925  to  sell  metallic  zinc  in  slabs,  in 
export  trade,  the  association  operated  suc- 
cessfully for  several  years.  One  of  the  mem- 
bers acted  as  forwarding  agent  for  all,  thereby 
effecting  a  saving  in  expense.  It  was  also 
reported  that  "by  operating  through  this  as- 
sociation our  members  had  the  advantage  of 
dealing  as  a  unit  with  foreign  competition  and 
were  enabled  to  more  readily  view  market 
conditions  abroad,  and  by  concentration  of 
information  and  ideas  were  able  to  arrive  at 
a  constructive  sales  policy  so  far  as  their  ex- 
port tonnage  was  concerned."  During  the 
depression,  however,  prices  abroad  were 
lower  than  those  in  the  United  States,  and 
the  members  were  unwilling  to  seU  at  the 
lower  levels.  The  association  was  inactive 
for  several  years,  for  this  reason,  and  was 
finally  dissolved  in  1934. 

Members  (stockholders) 

American  Metal  Co.,  Ltd.,  The,  New  York 

American  Zinc,  Lead  &  Smelting  Co.,  Boston, 
Mass.,  and  St.  Louis,  Mo 


1925-34 
1925-34 


13 


1920-23 


13 


1925-34 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEtR 


233 


120  ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  EXPORT  TRADE 
ACT,  APRIL  1918  TO  DECEMBER  1939,  REPRESENTING 
2,074  MEMBER  COMPANIES— Continued 


Zinc  Export  Association,  Inc. — Cnntinued. 

Athletic  Mining  &  Smelting  Co.,  Joplin,  Mo._ 
Eagle-Picher  Lead  Co.,  The,  Chicago,  111.,  and 

Cincinnati,  Ohio 

Fort  Smith  Spelter  Co.,  The,  Greencastle,  Ind- 
Grasselli  Chemical  Co.,  The,  Cleveland,  Ohio- 

Hegeler  Zinc  Co.,  The,  DanviUe,  111 

Illinois  Zinc  Co.,  Chicago,  111 

Kusa  Spelter  Co.,  Kansas  City,  Mo 

Matthiessen  &  Hegeler  Zinc  Co.,  La  Salle,  111. 

Quinton  Spelter  Co.,  The,  Joplin,  Mo 

United  Metals  Selling  Co.,  New  York 

United  Zinc  Smelting  Corporation,  New  York. 


Years 


1925-30 

1925-34 
1925-34 
1925-34 
1925-34 
1925-33 
1929-33 
1925-32 
1925-31 
1927-28 
1925-34 


Total  nnin- 

ber  of 
members 


Period  of 
associ- 
ation 
oftera- 
tioo 


EXHIBIT  4 

[First  Report  Form] 

Federal  Trade  Commission 
washington,  d.  c. 

FIRST  REPORT  FROM  EXPORT  ASSOCIATIONS 

DUE  WITHIN  30  DAYS  AFTER  CREATION 

1.  Name 

Addreiss 

(Here  Insert  address  of  principal  office) 

2.  Statement. — This  corporation  or  association  was  organized  or 
entered  into  for  the  sole  purpose  of  engaging  in  export  trade  and  is 
now  or  about  to  be  solely  engaged  in  the  export  trade  as  defined  in  the 
Export  Trade  Act,  approved  April  10,  1918,  viz :  "Trade  or  commerce 
in  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise  exported  or  in  the  course  of  being 
exported  from  the  United  States  or  any  territory  thereof,  to  any 
foreign  nation." 

3.  There  is  hereunto  an^.exed  and  made  a  part  hereof  a  schedule 
showing  in  paragraph  "A"  the  location  of  its  offices  or  places  of  busi- 
ness; in  paragraph  "B,"  the  names  and  addresses  of  all  its  officers 
and  directors;  in  paragraph  "C,"  the  names  and  addresses  of  all  its 
stockholders  or  members;  in  paragraph  "D,"  the  products  to  be  ex- 
ported; and  in  paragraph  "E,"  the  capital  authorized  and  paid  in. 

4.  There  is  also  annexed  (F)  a  brief  statement  describing  its 
methods  and  plan  under  which  it  is  doing  business,  a  statement  of  its 
relations  with  other  associations,  corporations,  and  individuals,  and 
such  other  information  as  this  company  or  association  deems  should 
be  in  the  export  files  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission. 

5.  If  a  corporation,  a  copy  of  its  certificate  or  articles  of  incorpora- 
tion and  by-laws  is  annexed  and  filed,  and  if  unincorporated,  a  copy  of 
its  articles  or  contract  of  association. 


By 

State  or 

Cov/nty  of ^ ,  ss: 

,  being  first  duly  sworn,  on  oath  deposes  and 

says  that  he  is  an  officer,  to  wit, of  the  above- 
named  corporation  or  association ;  that  he  has  read  the  foregoing  re- 
port and  schedules  annexed,  and  that  the  same  are  in  all  respects  true 
and  correct. 


(Verlftfing  officer  sign  here) 

Subscribed  and  sworn  to  before  me  this day  of ,  19__. 


Notary  Public. 
234 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  235 

Schedule  1 

(A)  The  following  are  the  locations  of  all  offices  and  places  of 
business : 


(B)  The  following  were  officers  or  directors,  as  of 

(Date) 

Names 

Office  Held 

Addresses 

(Date) 

Names 

Addresses 

Number  of  Shares 

(D)  It  desires  to  be  classified  as  engaged  in  exporting  the  follow- 
ing products,  viz: 

(Please   limit  to  products  now  or  about  to  be  exported  and  supplement  by  letter  when 

others  are  taken  on) 

(E)  Capital: 

(1)  Authorized  preferred,  $ ;  par  value,  $ ;  issued,  $ — ; 

paid  in,  $ 

(2)  Authorized  common,  $ ;  par  value,  $ ;  issued,  $ — ; 

paid  in,  $ 


(F)  The  following  briefly  describes  the  methods  and  plan  under 
which  our  business  is  done  and  states  our  relations  with  other  asso- 
ciations, corporations,  and  individuals,  with  such  other  information 
as  we  deem  should  be  in  the  export  files  of  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission : 


Notes 

1.  The  information  required  by  this  report  is  to  be  furnished  to 
the  Federal  Trade  Commission  under  "An  act  to  promote  export 


236  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

trade,  and  for  other  purposes,"  approved  April  10,  1918  (the  Export 
Trade  Act) ,  which  provides  in  section  5  thereof  as  follows : 

Sec.  5.  That  every  association  now  engaged  solely  in  export  trade,  within 
sixty  days  after  the  passage  of  this  Act,  and  every  association  entered  into 
hereafter  which  engages  solely  in  export  trade,  within  thirty  days  after  its 
creation,  shall  file  with  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  a  verified  written  state- 
ment setting  forth  the  location  of  its  oflSces  or  places  of  business  and  the  names 
and  addresses  of  all  its  officers  and  of  all  its  stockholders  or  members,  and  if 
a  corporation,  a  copy  of  its  certificate  or  articles  of  corporation  and  by-laws,  and 
if  unincorporated,  a  copy  of  its  articles  or  contract  of  association,  and  on  the 
first  day  of  January  of  each  year  thereafter  it  shall  make  a  like  statement  of 
the  location  of  its  offices  or  places  of  business  and  the  names  and  addresses  of 
all  its  officers  and  of  all  its  stockholders  or  members  and  of  all  amendments  to 
and  changes  in  its  articles  or  certificate  of  incorporation  or  in  its  articles  or 
contract  of  association.  It  shall  also  furnish  to  the  commission  such  informa- 
tion as  the  commission  may  require  as  to  its  organization,  business,  conduct, 
practices,  management,  and  relation  to  other  associations,  corporations,  partner- 
ships, and  individuals.  Any  association  which  shall  fail  so  to  do  shall  not 
have  the  benefit  of  the  provisions  of  section  two  and  section  three  of  this 
Act,  and  it  shall  also  forfeit  to  the  United  States  the  sum  of  $100  for  each  and 
every  day  of  the  continuance  of  such  failure,  which  forfeiture  shall  be  payable 
into  the  Treasury  of  the  United  States,  and  shall  be  recoverable  in  a  civil  suit 
in  the  name  of  the  United  States  brought  in  the  district  where  the  association 
has  its  principal  office,  or  in  any  district  in  which  it  shall  do  business.  It  shall 
be  the  duty  of  the  various  district  attorneys,  under  the  direction  of  the  Attorney 
Oeneral  of  the  United  States,  to  prosecute  for  the  recovery  of  the  forfeiture. 
The  costs  and  expenses  of  such  prosecution  shall  be  paid  out  of  the  appropria- 
tion for  the  expenses  of  the  courts  of  the  United  States.    *    *    * 

2.  The  word  "association"  wherever  used  in  the  "export  trade  act" 
or  in  this  report  means  "any  corporation  or  combination,  by  contract 
or  otherwise,  of  two  or  more  persons,  partnerships,  or  corporations." 


EXHIBIT  5 

[Annual  Report  Form] 

Federal  Trade  Commission 

washington,  d.  c. 

KEPORT  FROM  EXPORT  ASSOCIATIONS 

DUE  JANUARY  1,   194__,  OF: 

1.  Name 

Address 

(Here  Insert  address  of  principal  oflBcer) 

2.  Statement. — This  corporation  or  association  was  organized  or 
entered  into  for  the  sole  purpose  of  engaging  in  export  trade  and  is  now 
solely  engaged  in  the  export  trade  as  defined  in  the  Export  Trade  Act, 
xipproved  April  10, 1918,  viz :  "Trade  or  commerce«in  goods,  wares,  or 
merchandise  exported  or  in  the  course  of  being  exported  from  the 
United  States  or  any  territory  thereof,  to  any  foreign  nation." 

3.  There  is  hereunto  annexed  and  made  a  part  hereof  a  schedule 
showing  in  paragraph  "A"  the  location  of  its  offices  or  places  of  busi- 
ness ,*inv.  :)aragraph  "B,"  the  names  and  addresses  of  all  its  officers  and 
directors ,« in  paragraph  "C,"  the  names  and  addresses  of  all  its  stock- 
holders or  members ;  in  paragraph  "D,"  all  amendments  to  and  changes 
in  its  articles  or  certificate  of  incorporation,  or  articles  or  contract  of 
association  and  bylaws,  since  its  last  report  to  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission 

4.  There  is  also  annexed  (E)  a  brief  statement  describing  its  metliods 
and  plan  under  which  it  is  doing  business,  a  statement  of  its  relations 
with  other  associations,  corporations,  and  individuals,  and  such  other 
information  as  this  company  or  association  deems  should  be  in  the 
export  files  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission. 


By 

State  of ^ 

Cov/nty  of ,  ss: 

,  being  first  duly  sworn,  on  oath  deposes  and 

says  that  he  is  an  officer,  to  wit, of  the  above- 
named  corporation  or  association ;  that  he  has  read  the  foregoing  re- 
port and  schedules  annexed  and  that  the  same  are  in  all  respects  true 
and  correct. 


(Verifying  officer  sign  here) 

Subscribed  and  sworn  to  before  me  this day  of , 

19_-. 


Notary  Public. 
F.  T.  C.  117. 

237 


238  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Schedule  1 

(A)  The  following  are  the  locations  of  all  offices  and  places  of 
business : 


(B)  The  following  were  officers  or  directors,  as  of  January  1, 194     r 

Names 

Office  held 

Addresses 

(C)  The  following  were  stockholders  or  members,  as  of  January  1, 
194     : 

Names 

Addresses 

Number  of  shares 

(D)  Since  the  last  report  to  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  the 
articles  of  or  certificate  of  incorporation,  articles  of  association,  and 
bylaws  have  been  amended  or  changed  as  follows : 


(E)  The  following  briefly  describes  the  methods  and  plan  under 
which  our  business  is  done  and  states  our  relations  with  other  associa- 
tions, corporations,  and  individuals,  with  such  other  information  as 
we  deeaii  should  be  in  the  export  files  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission : 


Notes 

1.  The  information  required  by  this  report  is  to  be  furnished  to 
the  Federal  Trade  Commission  under  "•An  act  to  promote  export 
trade,  and  for  other  purposes,"  approved  April  10,  1918  (the  Export 
Trade  Aci)   which  provides  in  section  5  thereof  as  follows: 

Sec.  5.  Thai  every  association  now  engaged  solely  in  export  ti*ade,  within  sixty 
days  after  the  passage  of  this  Act,  and  every  association  entered  into  hereafter 
which  engages  soU  1y  in  export  trade,  within  thirty  days  after  its  creation,  shall 
file  with  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  a  verified  written  statement  setting 
forth  the  location  of  its  offices  or  places  of  business  and  the  names  and  addresses 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EXX)NOMIC  POWEH  239 

of  all  its  officers  and  of  all  its  stockholders  or  members,  and  if  a  corporation,  a 
copy  of  its  certificate  or  articles  of  incorporation  and  bylaws,  and  if  unincorpo- 
rated, a  copy  of  its  articles  or  contract  of  association,  and  on  the  first  day  of 
January  of  each  year  thereafter  it  Shall  make  a  like  statement  of  the  location 
of  its  offices  or  places  of  business  and  the  names  and  addresses  of  all  its  officers 
and  of  all  its  stockholders  or  members  and  of  all  amendments  to  and  changes 
in  its  articles  or  certificate  of  incorporation  or  in  its  articles  or  contract  of 
association.  It  shall  also  furnish  to  the  commission  such  information  as  the 
commission  may  require  as  to  its  organization,  business,  conduct,  practices, 
nanagement,  and  relation  to  other  associations,  corporations,  partnerships,  and 
ndividuals.  Any  association  which  shall  fail  so  to  do  shall  not  have  the  benefit 
(f  the  provisions  of  section  two  and  section  three  of  this  Act,  and  it  shall  also 
j'orfeit  to  the  United  States  the  sum  of  $100  for  each  and  every  day  of  the 
continuance  of  such  failure,  which  forfeiture  shall  be  payable  into  the  Treasury 
of  the  United  States,  and  shall  be  recoverable  in  a  civil  suit  in  the  name  of  the 
United  States  brought  in  the  district  where  the  association  has  its  principal  oflice, 
orvin  any  district  in  which  it  shall  do  business.  It  shall  be  the  duty  of  the 
various  district  attorneys,  under  the  direction  of  tlie  Attorney  General  of  the 
United  States,  to  prosecute  for  the  recovery  of  the  forfeiture.  The  costs  and 
expenses  of  such  prosecution  shall  be  paid  out  of  the  aonropriation  for  the  ex- 
penses of  the  courts  of  the  United  States.     *     *     * 

2.  The  word  "association"  wherever  used  in  the  "export  trade  act" 
or  in  this  report  means  "any  corporation  or  combination,  by  contract 
or  otherwise,  of  two  or  more  persons,  partnerships,  or  corporations." 


EXHIBIT  6 


[Federal  Trade  Commission,  Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  1] 

DISCUSSION  OF  AND  PRACTICE  AND  PROCEDURE  UN- 
DER  THE    EXPORT    TRADE   ACT    (WEBB-POMERENE 

LAW),  1919 


1.  Practice  and  Procedure. 

2.  Discussion    of    the    Export   Trade 

Act. 

3.  An  Act  to  Promote  Export  Trade 

(Webb  Law;   Public,   126,   65th 
Cong.). 


4.  Sections  73,  76,  and  77,  WUson  Tariff 

Act    (approved    August    27,    1894, 
amended  February  12,  1913). 

5.  Section  6   (h)    Federal  Trade  Com- 

mission   Act     (foreign     investiga- 
tions). 


Practice  and  Procedure 

•  The  very  numerous  requests  for  copies  of  the  Exf)ort  Trade  Act 
(Webb-Pomerene  law)  and  the  large  number  of  inquiries  about  it  call 
for  the  publication  of  a  separate  pamplilet  by  this  Commission  for  the 
information  of  those  desiring  to  cooperate  in  the  development  of  our 
foreign  trade  through  associations  formed  under  that  act. 

In  several  instances  suggestions  have  been  made  as  to  modifications 
of  proposed  articles  of  incorporation,  already  filed,  in  order  that 
these  associations  may  clearly  come  witb.in  the  provisions  of  the  act. 
The  Commission  is  authorized  by  this  law  to  make  recommendations 
as  to  how  export  associations  may  conform  their  business  to  the  law, 
and,  within  its  powers,  it  proposes  to  advance  step  by  step  in  aid  of 
the  export  needs  of  the  country.  It  desires  to  constantly  work  in 
cooperation  with  those  who  form  export  associations  and  also  with 
those  who  may  consider  themselves  or  the  public  in  any  way  injur- 
iously affected  by  the  methods  and  practices  of  such  associations. 

Where  doubt  exists  as  to  whether  a  given  method  or  practice  is 
proper  or  not,  it  would  seem  advisable  that  the  matter  be  voluntarily 
presented  to  the  Commission  in  the  early  stages,  without  awaiting  its 
later  discovery  and  possible  correction.  The  second  paragi-aph  of 
section  5  of  the  Webb  Act  describes  the  few  formalities  as  to  such 
procedure. 

The  Commission  has  prepared  blanks,  available  on  request,  for 
making  the  first  and  1919  annual  report  which  enables  an  easier 
compliance  with  section  5  of  the  Webb  Act. 

Should  it  become  necessary  for  an  export  association,  or  for  others 
engaged  in  the  export  trade,  to  seek  the  enforcement  of  the  Commis- 
sion's power  to  prevent  unfair  methods  of  competition  under  section  4 
of  the  Webb  Act,  the  rules  of  practice  do  not  require  formalities  in  the 
filing  of  information  or  the  lodging  of  complaints,  but  it  is  worth 
remembering  that  the  fuller  and  more  exact  the  information  and 
references  as  to  proof  thereof,  the  speedier  the  results  before  the  Com- 
mission. This  is  especially  true  where  the  charges  come  from  foreign 
240 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  241 

countries  where  the  time  necessary  for  transmission  might  render  the 
case  academic  through  the  sheer  lapse  of  time.  Wliere  allegations 
come  from  abroad  the  procedure  of  the  Conmiission  can  be  more 
quickly  set  in  motion  if  the  papers  are  in  such  condition  as  to  give  the 
Commission  "reason  to  believe"  that  alleged  facts  exist.  Copies  of 
letters,  advertisements,  exhibits,  and  affidavits  are  extremely  helpful, 
as  also  the  names  of  witnesses  and  sources  of  information  both  in  this 
country  and  abroad. 

As  the  Commission  can  proceed  on  its  own  initiative,  it  is  immate- 
rial from  what  source  its  information  is  derived,  but  it  is  desirable, 
wherever  possible,  that  for  its  confidential  use  the  informant  be  known. 

The  Commission's  investigation  of  foreign  conditions,  practices, 
and  combinations  in  foreign -countries  and  its  recommendations  to 
Congress  thereon  will  be  greatly  facilitated  by  American  export- 
ers keeping  the  Commission  informed  of  their  experiences  and  in- 
stances where  their  export  business  is  restrained  or  injuriously  af- 
fected by  any  matter  or  in  any  manner. 

The  Commission  must  depend  largely  for  information  and  facts 
upon  those  who  are  interested  in  having  the  Commission  correct  any 
tendencies  of  export  associations  to  artificially  enhance  or  depress 
prices  within  the  United  States  or  otherwise  burden  the  American 
public  or  restrain  the  commerce  of  independent  competitors. 

All  mail  for  the  Export  Division  should  be  addressed  to  the  Fed- 
eral Trade  Commission,  Washington,  D.  C,  and  marked  "Export 
Division." 

DISCUSSION  OF  THE  EXPORT  TRADE  ACT 

Swmmary  of  the  law. — Under  the  Export  Trade  Act,  approved 
April  10,  1918,  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  is  authorized  to  re- 
ceive, and  "associations"  now,  or  hereafter,  solely  engaged  in  export 
trade  are  required  to  file  statements  in  the  form  specified  by  the  act. 
The  Commission  is  given  authority  to  investigate  all  instances  where 
it  has  reason  to  believe  that  an  export  trade  "association"  has  com- 
mitted an  act,  or  made  an  agreement,  which  is  in  restraint  of  trade 
within  the  United  States,  or  which  is  in  restraint  of  the  export  trade 
of  any  domestic  competitor  of  such  "association."  This  applies  also 
where  such  an  "association"  has  entered  into  any  agreement,  under- 
standing, conspiracy,  or  done  any  act  in  the  United  States  or  else- 
where, which  artificially  enhances  or  depresses  prices  within  the 
United  States  of  commodities  exported  by  such  association,  or  where 
the  same  substantially  lessens  competition  within  the  United  States, 
or  otherwise  restrains  trade  therein.  In  such  event  the  offending 
"association,"  its  officers,  and  agents  may  be  summoned  before  the 
Commission,  and  it  is  thereupon  required  to  conduct  an  investigation 
into  the  alleged  violation  of  law.  If  upon  investigation  the  Com- 
mission concludes  that  the  law  has  been  violated  it  may  recommend 
to  the  "association"  readjustment  of  its  business  in  order  that  it  may 
thereafter  maintain  its  organization,  management,  and  the  conduct 
of  its  business  in  accordance  with  the  law. 

Where  an  association  fails  to  comply  with  the  recommendation 
of  the  Commission,  the  Commission  is  required  to  refer  its  findings 
and  recommendations  to  the  Attorney  General  of  tlie  United  States 
for  such  action  thereon  as  he  may  deem  proper. 


242  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

By  section  4  of  the  Export  Trade  Act  the  prohibition  in  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission  Act  against  unfair  methods  of  competition,  and 
the  remedies  provided  for  enforcing  said  prohibition,  are  directed 
to  be  construed  as  extending  to  unfair  methods  of  competition  used 
in  export  trade  against  competitors  engaged  in  such  trade,  even 
thoigh  the  acts  constituting  such  unfair  methods  are  done  without 
the  territorial  jurisdiction  of  the  United  States. 

The  act  defines  the  term  "export  trade"  wherever  used  in  the 
act  as  follows : 

The  words  "export  tidde"  wherever  used  in  this  act  mean  solely  trade  or 
commerce  in  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise  exported,  or  in  the  course  of  being 
exported  from  the  United  States  or  any  Territory  thereof,  to  any  foreign  nation ; 
but  the  words  "export  trade"  shall  not  be  deemed  to  include  the  production, 
manufacture,  or  selling  for  consumption  or  for  resale,  within  the  United  States 
or  any  Territory  thereof,  of  such  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise,  or  any  act  in 
the  course  of  such  production,  manufacture,  or  selling  for  consumption  or  for 
resale. 

The  words  "trade  within  the  United  States"  wherever  used  in  the 
act  are  defined  to  mean  trade  or  commerce  among  the  several  States 
or  in  any  Territory  of  the  United  States,  or  in  the  District  of  Co- 
lumbia, or  between  any  such  Territory  and  another,  or  between  any 
such  Territory  or  Territories  and  any  State  or  States  or  the  District 
of  Columbia,  or  between  the  District  of  Columbia  and  any  State  or 
States. 

The  word  "association"  wherever  used  in  the  act  is  defined  to  mean : 

Any  corporation  or  combination,  by  contract  or  otherwise,  of  two  or  more 
persons,  partnerships,  or  corporat'ors. 

Under  section  5  of  the  act  a  penalty  is  imposed  upon  any  associa- 
tion which  shall  fail  to  make  the  statement  and  furnish  the  state- 
ments reqitired  to  be  filed,  and  also  furnish  the  Commission  with  such 
information  as  it  may'require,  as  to  the  organization,  business,  con- 
duct,, practices,  management,  and  relation  to  other  associations,  cor- 
porations, partnerships,  and  individuals  of  such  associations.  The 
penalty  imposed  for  failure  to  comply  with  section  5  of  this  act  is 
that  the  association  shall  not  have  the  benefit  of  the  provisions  of 
sections  2  and  3  of  the  act,  and  shall  forfeit  to  the  United  States  $100 
per  da}^  during  the  continuance  of  such  failure  to  comply  with  its 
terms.  This  forfeiture  is  payable  into  the  Treasury  of  the  United 
States  and  is  recoverable  in  a  civil  suit  in  the  name  of  the  United 
States,  in  the  district  where  the  association  has  its  principal  office,  or 
in  any  district  in  which  it  shall  do  business,  by  the  district  attorney 
under  the  direction  of  the  Attorney  General  of  the  United  States, 
and  the  costs  and  expenses  of  such  prosecutions  are  payable  out  of 
the  appropriation  for  the  expense  of  the  courts  of  the  United  States. 

Under  section  2  of  the  Export  Trade  Act,  the  provisions  of  the 
Sherman  law,  approved  July  2,  1890,  are  directed  to  be  construed  in 
such  a  way  that  nothing  therein  contained  shall  declare  to  be  illegal 
"associations"  entered  into  for  the  sole  purpose  of  engaging  in  export 
trade  and  actually  engaged  solely  in  such  export  trade,  nor  any  agree- 
ment made,  or  act  done  in  the  course  of  such  export  trade  by  such 
an  association,  provided  such  agreement  or  act  is  not  in  restraint  of 
trade  within  the  United  States,  and  is  not  in  restraint  of  the  export 
trade  of  any  domestic  competitor  of  such  an  association;  provided. 


CONCENTKATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR  243 

however,  that  such  association  does  not,  either  in  the  United  States 
or  elsewhere,  enter  into  any  agreement,  understanding,  or  conspiracy, 
or  do  any  act  which  artificially  or  intentionally  enhances  or  depresses 
prices  within  the  United  States  of  commodities  of  the  class  exported 
by  such  association,  or  which  substantially  lessens  competition  within 
the  United  States  or  otherwise  restrains  trade  therein. 

By  section  3  of  the  act  it  is  directed  that  section  7  of  the  Clayton  Act, 
approved  October  15, 1914,  shall  not  be  cons!  rued  to  forbid  the  acquisi- 
tion or  ownership  by  any  corporation  of  the  whole  or  any  part  of  the 
stock  or  other  capital  of  any  corporation  organized  solely  for  the  pur- 
pose of  engaging  in  export  trade,  and  actually  engaged  solely  in  such 
export  trade,  unless  the  effect  of  such  acquisition  or  ownership  may 
be  to  restrain  trade  or  substantially  lessen  com.petition  within  the 
United  States. 

Form  of  statement. — For  the  convenience  of  those  who  desire  to  file 
the  statement  required  by  section  5  of  the  act  there  have  been  prepared 
and  printed  forms  of  statement,  which  are  available  upon  application. 

Applications  for  coTistmetion  of  the  act. — Numerous  requests  have 
been  received  by  the  Commission  for  rulings  upon  the  construction  of 
the  Export  Trade  Act.  It  has  been  deemed  inadvisable  to  attempt  at 
this  time  to  officially  construe  any  of  the  provisions  of  the  law  upon 
informal  applications.  This  is  especially  true,  as  the  penalty  for  the 
violation  of  section  5  of  the  act  is  enforcible  by  the  district  attorneys 
of  the  United  States  under  the  direction  of  the  Attorney  General,  and 
not  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  and  the  enforcement  of  the 
Sherman  law  is  a  duty  of  the  Federal  courts  upon  proceedings 
instituted  b}'  the  Department  of  Justice. 

It  is  exceedingly  important  that  export  associations  in  process  of 
formation  should  give  careful  consideration  to  the  wording  of  sections 
2  and  3  of  the  Export  Trade  Act.  As  to  the  statements  which  have 
been  filed  with  the  Export  Trade  Division  under  section  5  of  this  act, 
it  has  been  noted  that  practically  every  corporation  formed  has  been 
organized  for  the  transaction  of  some  business  other  than  that  of  solely 
engaging  in  exporting  from  the  United  States  to  foreign  nations  as 
defined  in  the  act. 

Most  of  tlie  articles  of  association  filed  have  also  contemplated  the 
transaction  of  business  other  than  that  of  exporting  to  foreign  nations. 
It  is  apparent  under  the  law  that  the  provisions  of  the  Sherman  law 
and  section  7  of  the  Clayton  law  remani  applicable  as  to  all  combina- 
tions which  are  not  organized  solely  for  the  business  of  exporting  to 
foreign  nations.  The  business  of  exporthig  to  the  Philippine  Islands, 
to  Puerto  Rico,  or  to  Hawaii  seems  clearly  to  be  domestic  and  not 
foreign  trade,  and  the  provisions  of  the  Sherman  law  and  section  7  of 
tlie  Clayton  law  seem  to  continue  in  force  as  to  any  association  or 
export  corporation  which  engages  in  such  business. 

One  of  the  difficulties  wliich  exporting  houses  seem  to  find  with  the 
law  is  that  export  companies  usually  both  export  and  import,  while 
the  law  provides  that  its  protection  is  given  to  associations  entered  mto 
for  the  sole  purpose  of  engaging  in  export  trade  and  actually  enga^>-ed 
solely  in  such  export  trade. 

Dae  to  the  facts  that  the  business  of  the  country  is  devoting  its 
thought  to  war  production  and  that  there  is  a  lack  of  shipping  facilities, 
general  plans  for  cooperation  in  export  trade  are  probably  now  in 

2." 7760 — il — No.  G 1-7 


244  CONCENTRATION  OF  EXX)NOMIC  POWER 

suspense  or  only  in  a  formative  state.  This  is  indicated  by  the  very 
small  number  of  association  papers  which  have  been  filed  with  the 
Commission  since  the  passage  of  the  act  on  April  10, 1918. 

Statements  filed. — Below  is  a  list  of  all  organizations  that  have  filed 
papers  purporting  to  be  under  section  5  of  the  Export  Trade  Act 
(April  10, 1918,  to  June  30, 1918,  inclusive). 

In  listing  them  the  Commission  doe-s  not  indicate  that  those  who 
have  filed  these  papers  are  qualified  under  the  act,  or  entitled  to  the 
benefits  of  sections  2  and  3  of  the  law.  Undoubtedly  many  export 
houses  have  felt  it  was  necessary  to  file  statements  to  avoid  any  ques- 
tion as  to  the  penalty  imposed  by  section  5  for  failure  so  to  do.  It  is 
also  probable  that  other  export  houses  considered,  without  a  thorough 
consideration  of  the  law,  that  they  could  obtain  some  advantage 
thereby. 

The  list  follows : 

Allied  Sugar  Machinery  Corporation,  120  Broadway,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Allied  Construction  Machinery  Corporation,  120'Broadway,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Allied  Machinery  Co.  of  America,  120  Broadway,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

American  International  Steel  Corporation,  120  Broadway,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

American  Paper  Exports  (Inc.),  30  Broad  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Amsinck  &  Co.,  S.  of  Mexico  (Inc.),  120  Broadway,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

American  Steel  Export  Co.,  Woolworth  Building,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

American  Steel  Export  Co.'s  Brazilian  Corporation,  Woolworth  Building,  New 
York,  N.  Y. 

American  Webbing  Manufacturing  Export  Corporation,  care  Clark  McKercher, 
Esq.,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Automotive  Products  Corporation,  Woolworth  Building,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Cosmo  "Trading  Co.,  133  West  Washington  Street,  Chicago,  111. 

Cranz  (Inc.),  F.,  2  Stone  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Cranz  Importing  Co.,  F.  E.,  2  Stone  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y, 

Deco  Co.,  51-53  White  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Deister  Miners'  Supply  Co.,  Fort  Wayne,  Ind. 

De  Lima,  Carrea  &  Cortissoz  (Inc.),  8-10  Bridge  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Dodge  &  Seymour,  12  Hudson  Place,  Hoboken,  N.  J.,  and 

Dodge  &  Seymour   (China,  Ltd.),  12  Hudson  Place,  Hoboken,  N.   J.,  a  subsid- 
iary company. 

Douglas  Fir  Exploitation  &  Export  Co.,  260  California  Street,  San  Francisco 
Calif. 

Dunnellon  Phosphate  Co.  (The),  106  East  Bay  Street,  Savannah,  Ga. 

European  &  Far-Eastern  Sales  Co.  (Inc.),  27  William  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Export  Trade  Association  vine),  Borough  of  Manhattan,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Factory  Products  Export  Cbrporation,  61  Broadway,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Fajardo  Bros.  &  Co.   (Inc.),  27  William  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Franklyn  International  Corporation,  958  Hoe  Avenue,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Galban  Noecker  &  Co.   (Inc.),  82-92  Beaver  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Galena  Signal  Oil  Co.  of  Brazil,  Franklin,  Pa. 

Harper  &  Co.,  Locke  T.,  MiUs  Building,  San  Francisco,  Calif. 

Herzberg  &  Son,  B.,  1119  Fillmore  Street.  San   Francisco,  Calif. 

Holsam  Co.  (Inc.),  18  Broadway,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

International  Clearing  House  of  New  York    (Inc.),  748  Broadway,  New  York, 
N.    Y. 

Levy  Co.   (Inc.),  A.  A.,  45  East  Nineteenth  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

M.  P.  Trading  Co.   (Inc.),  60  Wall  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Manufacturers  Agents  Co.    (Inc.),  Virginia  Railway  &  Power  Building,  Rich- 
mond, Va. 

Markt  &  Hammacher  Co.,  193  West  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Markt  &  Schafer  Co..  193  West  Street,  New  York.  N.  Y. 

Mexican  Importing  &  Exporting  Corporation,  29  Broadway,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Muller,  Maclean  &  Co.   (Inc.),  11  Broadway,  New  York.  N.  Y. 

Parsons  &  Whittemore  (Inc.),  174  Fulton  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Portuguese-American  Exporters    (Inc.),  120  Broadway,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Pan  American  Exporters  (Inc.),  517  (iodschaux'^ Building,  New  Orleans,  La. 


.    CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  245 

Pan  American  Trading  Co.,  45  Pearl  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 
Pearson  Elxport  Corporation,  170  Broadway,  New  Yorl£,  N.  Y. 
Peek  &  Co.,  William  E.,  104  Pearl  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 
Redwood  Export  Co.,  260  California  Street,  San  Francisco,  Calif. 
Semtec  (Ltd.),  90  West  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 

Simmons  Co.,  Thomas  W.,  240  California  Street,  San  Francisco,  Calif. 
Southern  Products  Co.,  Interurban  Building,  Dallas,  Tex. 
Sparks  &  Co.,  W.  J.,  17  Battery  Place,  New  York,  N  .Y. 
Strong  &  Trowbridge  Co.,  17  Battery  Place,  New  York,  N.  Y. 
Sydney  Ross  Co.,  147-153  Waverly  Place,  New  York,  N.  Y. 
Texas  Co.  (South  America)    (Ltd.),  The,  17  Battery  Place,  New  York,  N.  Y. 
United  States  Paper  Export  Association,  30  Broad  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 
United  States  Office  Equipment  Export  Assn.,  care  Globe  Wernicke  Co.,  Cin- 
cinnati,  Ohio. 
Zaldo  &  Martinez  Co.  (Inc.),  66  Beaver  Street,  New  York,  N.  Y. 
Zoccola  Co.  (Inc.),  60  South  Street,  Boston,  Mass. 

Some  fear  has  been  expressed  in  South  American  countries  that  the 
effect  of  the  Export  Trade  Act  will  be  disadvantageous  to  the  con 
suming  public  of  foreign  nations  by  strengthening  the  hands  of 
American  trusts,  monopolies,  and  combinations  of  capital  in  these 
markets.  The  Commission  has  pointed  out  the  fact  that  the  law- 
permits  the  •  cooperation  of  manufacturers  who  would  perhaps  not 
otherwise  be  able  to  compete  in  foreign  fields  and  who,  without  the 
law,  might  hesitate  to  form  cooperative  export  associations,  which 
will  in  all  probability  increase  the  buying  opportunities  of  the  con- 
suming public  in  foreign  countries. 

The  Commission  has  been  cooperating  with  the  Bureau  of  Foreign 
and  Domestic  Commerce  and  has  availed  itself  of  the  privilege  of 
publishing  in  Commerce  Reports  statements  from  time  to  time. 

The  Commission  is  keeping  informed  as  to  the  export  needs  of  the 
country  in  order  to  be  of  assistance  so  that  American  producers  may 
cooperate  to  the  fullest  extent  in  export  fields  without  injuriously 
affecting  domestic  commerce  or  the  foreign  commerce  of  those  ex- 
porters who  are  associated  with  export  trade  associations. 

Progress  has  been  made  in  the  preparation  of  an  additional  report 
on  foreign  trade  conditions  under  section  6,  clause  H,  of  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission  Act,  reading  as  follows : 

Seo.  6.  That  the  Commission  shall  also  have  power — 

(h)  To  investigate,  from  time  to  time,  trade  conditions  in  and  with  foreign 

countries  where  associations,  combinations,  or  practices  of  manufacturers,  raer- 

'  chants,   or  traders,   or  other  conditions,  may   affect  the  foreign   trade  of  the 

United  States,  and  to  report  to  Congress  thereon,  with  such  recommendations  as 

it  deems  advisable. 

The  werld-wide  dislocation  of  trade  and  industry  incident  to  the 
war  is  creating  new  conditions  which  may  vitally  affect  American 
business  in  the  future.  The  Connnission  is  closely  following  new 
developments  in  international  trade,  as  they  arise,  with  a  view  to 
ascertaining  the  bearing  they  may  have  on  the  foreign  trade  of  the 
United  States. 

[Public — No.  126 — 65th  Congress] 

[H.  R.  2316] 

AN  ACT  To  promote  export  trade,  and  for  other  purposes 

Be  it  enacted  hy  the  Senate  and  House  of  Representatives  of  the 
Umted  States  of  America  in  Congress  asseinhltd.  Tliat  the  words  ''fx- 


246  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

port  trade"  wherever  used  in  this  act  mean  solely  trade  or  commerce 
in  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise  exported,  or  in  the  course  of  being 
exported,  from  the  United  States  or  ^ny  Territory  thereof  to  any 
foreign  nation ;  but  the  words  "export  trade"  shall  not  be  deemed  to 
include  the  production,  manufacture,  or  selling  for  consumption  or  for 
resale,  within  the  United  States  or  any  Territory  thereof,  of  such 
goods,  wares,  or  merchandise,  or  any  act  in  the  course  of  such  produc- 
tion, manufacture,  or  selling  for  consumption  or  for  resale. 

That  thd  words  "trade  within  the  United  States"  wherever  used 
in  this  act  mean  trade  or  commerce  among  the  several  States  or  in 
any  Territory  of  the  United  States,  or  in  the  District  of  Columbia, 
or  between  any  such  Territory  and  another,  or  between  any  such 
Territory  or  Territories  and  any  State  or  States  or  the  District  of  Co- 
lumbia, or  between  the  District  of  Columbia  and  any  State  or  States. 

That  the  word  "association"  wherever  used  in  this  act  means  any 
corporation  or  combination,  by  contract  or  otherwise,  of  two  or  more 
persons,  partnerships,  or  corporations. 

Sec.  2.  That  nothing  contained  in  the  act  entitled  "An  act  to  protect 
trade  and  commerce  against  unlawful  restraints  and  monopolies," 
approved  July  second,  eighteen  hundred  and  ninety,^  shall  be  con- 
strued a^;  declaring  to  be  illegal  an  association  entered  into  for  the 
sole  purpose  of  engaging  in  export  trade  and  actually  engaged  solely 
in  such  export  trade,  or  an  agreement  made  or  act  done  in  the  course  of 
export  trade  by  such  association,  provided  such  association,  agreement, 
or  act  is  not  in  restraint  of  trade  within  the  United  States,  and  is  not  in 
restraint  of  the  export  trade  of  any  domestic  competitor  of  such  asseci- 
ation :  Aiid  provided  further^  That  such  association  does  not,  either  in 
the  United  States  or  elsewhere,  enter  into  any  agreement,  understand- 
ing, or  conspiracy,  or  do  any  act  which  artificially  or  intentionally 
enhances  or  depresses  prices  within  the  United  States  of  commodities 
of  the  class  exported  by  such  association,  or  which  substantially  lessens 
competition  within  the  United  States  or  otherwise  restrains  trade 
therein. 

Sec.  3.  That  nothing  contained  in  section  seven  of  the  act  entitled 
"An  act  to  supplement  existing  laws  against  unlawful  restraints  and 
monopolies,   and   for  other  purposes,"   approved   October   fifteenth, 


1  Tlie  Sherman  Act  provides  in  sections  1,  2,  and  3  as  follows  : 

Section  1.  Every  contract,  combination  in  the  form  of  trust  or  otherwise,  or  con- 
spiracy, in  I'cstraint  of  trade  or  commerce  among  the  several  States,  or  with  foreign 
nations,  is  hereby  declared  to  be  illegal.  Every  person  who  shall  make  any  such  contract 
or  engage  in  any  such  combination  or  conspiracy,  shall  be  deemed  guilty  of  a  misde- 
meanor, and,  on  con\  iction  thereof,  shall  be  punished  by  fine  not  exceeding  five  thousand 
dollars,  or  by  imprisonment  not  exceeding  one  year,  or  "by  both  said  punishments,  in  the 
discietion  of  the  court. 

Sec.  2.  Every  person  who  shall  monopolize  or  attempc  to  monopolize,  or  combine  or 
conspire  with  any  other  person  or  persons,  to  monopolize  an.v  part  of  the  trade  or  com- 
merce among  the  several  States,  or  with  foreign  nations,  shall  be  deemed  guilty  of  a 
misdemeanor,  and,  on  conviction  thereof,  shall  be  punished  by  fine  not  exceeding  five 
thousand  dollars,  or  by  imprisonment  not  exceeding  one  year,  or  by  both  said  punishments, 
in  the  discretion  of  the  court. 

Sec.  3.  Every  contract,  combination  in  form  of  trust  or  otherwise,  or  conspiracy,  in 
restraint  of  trade  or  commerce  in  any  Territory  of  the  United  States  or  of  the  District 
of  Columbia,  or  in  restraint  of  trade  or  commerce  between  any  such  Territory  and 
another,  or  between  any  such  Territory  or  Territories  and  any  State  or  States  or  the 
District  of  Columbia,  or  with  foreign  nations,  or  between  the  District  of  Columbia  and 
any  State  or  States  or  foreign  nations,  is  hereby  declared  illegal.  Every  person  who 
shall  make  any  such  contract  or  engage  in  any  such  combination  or  conspiracy  shall  be 
deemed  guilty  of  a  misdemeanor,  and,  on  conviction  thereof,  shall  be  punished  by  fine 
not  exceeding  five  thousand  dollars,  or  by  imprisonment  not  exceeding  one  year,  or  by 
both  said  punishments,  in  the  discretion  of  the  court. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEK  247 

nineteen  hundred  and  fourteen,^  shall  be  construed  to  forbid  the 
acquisition  or  ownership  by  any  corporation  of  the  whole  or  any 
part  of  the  stock  or  other  capital  of  any  corporation  organized  solely 
for  the  purpose  of  engaging  in  export  trade,  and  actually  engaged 
solely  in  such  export  trade,  unless  the  effect  of  such  acquisition  or 
ownership -may  be  to  restrain  trade  or  substantially  lessen  competition 
within  the  United  States. 

Sec,  4.  That  the  prohibition  against  "unfair  methods  of  competi- 
tion" and  the  remedies  provided  for  inforcing  said  prohibition  con- 
tained in  the  act  entitled  "An  act  to  create  a  Federal  trade  commission, 
to  define  its  powers  and  duties,  and  for  other  purposes,"  approved 
September  twenty-sixth,  nineteen  hundred  and  fourteen,^  shall  be  con- 


'  Section  7  of  the  Clayton  Act  reads  as  follows  : 

Sec.  7.  That  no  corporation  encaged  in  commerce  shall  acquire,  directly  or  indirectly, 
the  whole  or  any  part  of  the  stock  or  other  share  capital  of  another  corporation  engaged 
also  in  commerce,  where  the  effect  of  such  acquisition  may  be  to  substantially  lessen 
competition  between  the  corporation  whose  stock  is  so  acquired  and  the  corporation 
making  the  acquisition,  or  to  restrain  such  commerce  in  any  section  or  community,  or 
tend  to  create  a  monopoly  of  any  line  of  commerce. 

No  corporation  shall  acquire,  directly  or  indirectly,  the  whole  or  any  part  of  the 
stock  or  other  share  capital  of  two  or  more  corporations  engaged  in  commerce  where  the 
effect  of  such  acquisition,  or  the  use  of  such  stock  by  the  voting  or  granting  of  proxies 
or  otherwise,  may  be  to  substantially  lessen  competition  between  such  corporations,  or 
any  of  them,  whose  stock  or  other  share  capital  is  so  acquired,  or  to  restrain  such  com- 
merce in  any  section  or  community,  or  tend  to  create  a  monopoly  of  any  line  of  commerce. 

This  section  shall  not  apply  to  corporations  purchasing  such  stock  solely  for  invest- 
ment and  not  using  the  same  by  voting  or  otherwise  to  bring  about,  or  in  attempting  to 
bring  about,  the  substantial  lessening  of  competition.  Nor  shall  anything  contained  in 
this  section  prevent  a  corporation  engaged  in  commerce  from  causing  the  formation  of 
subsidiary  corporations  for  the  actual  carrying  on  of  their  immediate  lawful  business, 
or  the  natural  and  legitimate  branches  or  extensions  thereof,  or  from  owning  and  holding 
all  or  a  part  of  the  stock  of  such  subsidiary  corporations,  when  the  effect  of  such 
formation  is  not  to  substantially  lessen  competition. 

Nor  shall  anything  herein  contained  be  construed  to  prohibit  any  common  carrier  sub- 
ject to  the  laws  to  regulate  commerce  from  aiding  in  the  construction  of  branches  or  short 
lines  so  located  as  to  become  feeders  to  the  main  line  of  the  company  so  aiding  in  such 
construction  or  from  acquiring  or  owning  all  or  any  part  of  the  stock  of  such  branch 
lines,  nor  to  prevent  any  such  common  carrier  from  acquiring  and  owning  all  or  any 
part  of  the  stock  of  a  branch  or  short  line  constructed  by  an  independent  company  where 
there  is  no  substantial  competition  between  the  company  owning  the  branch  line  so  con- 
structed and  the  company  owning  the  main  line  acquiring  the  property  or  an  interest 
therein,  nor  to  prevent  such  common  carrier  from  extending  any  of  its  lines  through  th« 
medium  of  the  acquisition  of  stock  or  otherwise  of  any  other  such  common  carrier  where 
there  is  no  substantial  competition  between  the  company  extending  its  lines  and  the 
company  whose  stock,  property,  or  an  interest  therein  is  so  acquired. 

Nothing  contained  in  this  section  shall  be  held  to  affect  or  impair  any  right  hereto- 
fore legally  acquired  :  Provided,  That  nothing  in  this  section  shall  b^  held  or  construed 
to  authorize  or  make  lawful  anything  heretofore  prohibited  or  made  illegal  by  the  anti- 
trust laws,  nor  to  exempt  any  person  from  the  penal  provisions  thereof  or  the  civil 
remedies  therein  provided. 

^  Section  .5  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act  reads  as  follows  : 

Sec.  5.  That  unfair  methods  of  competition  in  commerce  are  hereby  declared  unlawful. 

The  commission  is  hereby  empowered  and  directed  to  prevent  persons,  partnerships,  or 
corporations,  except  banks,  and  common  carriers  subject  to  the  acts  to  regulate  commerce, 
from  using  uhfair  methods  of  competition  in  commerce. 

Whenever  the  commission  shall  have  reason  to  believe  that  any  such  person,  partner- 
ship, or  corporation  has  been  or  is  u.<ing  any  unfair  method  of  competition  in  commerce, 
and  if  it  shall  appear  to  the  commission  that  a  proceeding  by  it  in  respect  thereof  would 
be  to  the  interest  of  the  public,  it  shall  issue  and  serve  upon  such  person,  partnership,  or 
corporation  a  complaint  stating  its  charge.^!  in  that  respect  and  containing  a  notice  of 
a  hearing  upon  a  day  and  at  a  place  therein  fixed  at  least  thirty  days  after  the  service 
of  said  complaint.  The  person,  partnership,  or  corporation  so  complained  of  shall  have 
the  right  to  appear  at  the  place  and  time  so  fixed  and  show  cause  why  an  order  should 
not  be  entered  by  the  commission  requiring  such  person,  partnership,  or  corporation  to 
cease  and  desist  from  tlie  violation  of  the  law  so  charged  in  said  complaint.  Any  person, 
partnership,  or  corporation  may  make  application,  and  upon  good  cause  shown  may  be 
allowed  by  the  commission  to  intervene  and  appear  in  said  proceeding  by  counsel  or  in 
persoi..  The  testimony  in  any  such  proceeding  shall  be  reduced  to  writing  and  filed  in 
the  office  of  the  commission.  If  upon  such  hearing  the  commission  shall  he  of  the 
opinion  that  the  method  of  competition  in  question  is  prohibited  by  this  act  it  shall 
make  a  report  in  writing  in  which  it  shall  state  its  findings  as  to  "the  facts  and  shall 
issue  and  cause  to  he  served  on  such  person,  partnership,  or  corporation  an  order  requir- 
ing such  person,  partnership,  or.  corporation  to  cease  and  desist  from  using  such  method 
of  competition.  Until  a  transcript  of  the  record  in  such  hearing  shall  have  been  filed 
in  a  circuit  court  of  appeals  of  the  I'nited  States,  as  hereinafter  provided,  the  commission 
may  at  any  time,  upon  such   notice  and  in  such  manner  as  it  shall  deem  proper,  modify 


248  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 

strued  as  extending  to  unfair  methods  of  competition  used  in  export 
tpade  against  competitors  engaged  in  export  trade,  even  though  the 
acts  constituting  such  unfair  methods  are  done  without  tlie  territorial 
jurisdiction  of  the  United  States. 

Sec,  5.  That  every  association  now  engaged  solely  in  export  trade, 
within  sixty  days  after  the  passage  of  this  act,  and  every  association 
entered  into  hereafter  which  engages  solely  in  export  trade,  within 
thirty  days  after  its  creation,  shall  file  with  the  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission a  verified  written  statement  setting  forth  the  location  of  its 
offices  or  places  of  business  and  the  names  and  addresses  of  all  its 
officers  and  of  all  its  stockholders  or  members,  and  if  a  corporation, 
a  copy  of  its  certificate  or  articles  of  incorporation  and  bylaws,  and 
if  unincorporated  u  copy  of  its  articles  or  contract  of  association,  and 
on  the  first  day  of  January  of  each  year  thereafter  it  shall  make  a  like 
statement  of  the  location  of  its  offices  or  places  of  business  and  the 
names  and  addresses  of  all  its  officers  and  of  all  its  stockholders  or 
members  and  of  all  amendments  to  and  changes  in  its  articles  or 
certificate  of  incorporation  or  in  its  articles  or  contract  of  association. 
It  shall  also  furnish  to  the  commission  such  information  as  the  com- 
mission may  require  as  to  its  organization,  business,  conduct,  practices, 

or  set  aside,  in  whole  or  in  part,  any  report  or  any  order  made  or  issued  by  it  under 
this  section. 

If  such  person,  partnership,  or  corporation  fails  or  neglects  to  obey  such  order  of  the 
commission  while  the  same  is  in  effect,  the  commission  may  apply  to  the  circuit  court 
of  appeals  of  the  United  States,  within  any  circuit  where  the  method  of  competition  In 
question  was  used  or  where  such  person,  partnership,  or  corporation  resides  or  carries  on 
business,  for  the  enforcement  of  its  order,  and  shall  certify  and  file  with  its  application 
a  transcript  of  the  entire  record  in  the  proceeding,  including  all  the  testimony  taken  and 
the  report  and  order  of  the  commission.  Upon  such  filing  of  the  application  and  tran- 
script tLe  court  shall  cause  notice  thereof  to  be  served  upon  such  person,  partnership,  or 
corporation  and  thereupon  shall  have  jurisdiction  of  the  proceieding  and  of  the  question 
determined  therein,  and  shall  have  power  to  make  and  enter  upon  the  pleadings,  testi- 
mony, and  proceedings  set  forth  in  sucli  transcript  a  decree  afflrming,  modifying,  or 
setting  aside  the  order  of  the  commission.  The  findings  of  the  commission  as  to  the 
facts,  if  supported  by  testimony,  shall  be  conclusive.  If  either  party  shall  apply  to  the 
court  for  leave  to  adduce  additional  evidence,  and  shall  show  to  the  satisfaction  of  the 
court  that  such  additional  evidence  is  material  and  that  there  were  reasonable  grounds 
for  the  failure  to  adduce  such  evidence  in  the  proceeding  before  the  commission,  the  court 
may  order  such  additional  evidence  to  be  taken  before  the  commission  and  to  be  adduced 
upon  the  hearing  in  such  manner  and  upon  such  terms  and  conditions  as  to  the  court  may 
seem  proper.  The  commission  may  modify  its  findings  as  to  the  facts,  or  make  new 
findings,  by  reason  of  the  additional  evidence  so  taken,  and  it  shall  file  such  modified  or 
new  findings,  which,  if  supported  by  testimony,  shall  be  conclusive,  and  its  recommenda- 
tion, if  any,  for  the  modification  or  setting  aside  of  its  original  order,  with  the  return  of 
such  additional  evidence.  The  judgment  and  decree  of  the  court  shall  be  final,  except 
that  the  same  shall  be  subject  to  review  by  the  Supreme  Court  upon  certiorari  as  provided 
in  section  two  hundred  and  forty  of  the  Judicial  Code. 

Any  party  required  by  such  order  of  the  commission  to  cease  and  desist  from  using  such 
method  of  competition  may  obtain  a  review  of  such  order  in  said  circuit  court  of  appeals 
.  by  filing  in  the  court  a  written  petition  praying  that  the  order  of  the  commission  be  set 
aside.  A  copy  of  such  petition  shall  be  forthwith  served  upon  the  commission,  and  there- 
upon the  commission  forthwith  shall  certify  and  file  in  the  court  a  transcript  of  the 
record  as  hereinbefore  provided.  Upon  the  filing  of  the  transcript  the  court  shall  have 
the  same  jurisdiction  to  affirm,  set  aside,  or  modify  the  order  of  the  commission  as  in  the 
case  of  an  application  by  the  commission  for  the  enforcement  of  its  order,  and  the  find- 
ings of  the  commission  as  to  the  facts,  if  supported  by  testimony,  shall  in  like  manner  be 
conclusive. 

The  jurisdiction  of  the  circuit  court  of  appeals  of  the  United  States  to  enforce,  set 
aside,  or  modify  orders  of  the  commis.sion  shall  be  exclusive. 

Such  proceedings  In  the  circuit  court  of  appeals  shall  be  given  precedence  over  other 
cases  pending  therein,  and  shall  be  in  every  way  expedited.  No  order  of  the  commission 
or  judgment  of  the  court  to  enforce  the  same  shall  in  anywise  relieve  or  absolve  any 
person,   partnership,  or  corporation  from  any  liability  under  the  antitrust  acts. 

Complaints,  orders,  and  other  processes  of  the  commission  under  this  section  may  be 
served  by  anyone  duly  authorized  by  the  commis.«sion,  either  (a)  by  delivering  a  copy 
thereof  to  the  person  to  be  served,  or  to  a  member  of  the  partnership  to  be  served,  or  to 
the  president,  secretary,  or  other  executive  officer  or  a  director  of  the  corporation  to  be 
served;  or  (6)  by  leaving  a  copy  thereof  at  the  principal  office  or  place  of  business  of 
such  person,  partnership,  or  corporation;  or  (c)  by  registering  and  mailing  a, copy  thereof 
addressed  to  such  person,  partnership,  or  corporation  at  his  or  its  principal  oTice  or  p'oce 
of  business.  The  verified  return  by  the  person  so  serving  said  complaint,  order,  or  other 
process  setting  forth  the  manner  of  said  service  shall  he  proof  of  the  same,  und  thn  recurs 
post-office  receipt  for  said  complaint,  order,  or  other  process  registered  end  iuai'ed  as 
aforesaid  shall  be  proof  of  the  service  of  the  same 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR  249 

management,  and  relation  to  other  associations,  corporations,  partner- 
ships, and  individuals.  Any  association  which  shall  fail  so  to  do  shall 
not  have  the  benefit  of  the  provisions  of  section  two  and  section  three 
of  this  act,  and  it  shall  also  forfeit  to  the  United  States  the  sum  of 
$100  for  each  and  every  day  of  the  continuance  of  such  failure,  which 
forfeiture  shall  be  payable  into  the  Treasury  of  the  United  States,  and 
shall  be  recoverable  in  a  civil  suit  in  the  name  of  the  United  States 
brought  in  the  district  where  the  association  has  its  principal  office,  or 
in  any  district  in  which  it  shall  do  business.  It  shall  be  the  duty  of  the 
various  district  attorneys,  under  the  direction  of  the  Attorney.  General 
of  the  United  States,  to  prosecute  for  the  recovery  of  the  forfeiture. 
The  costs  and  expenses  of  such  prosecution  shall  be  paid  out  of  the 
appropriation  for  the  expenses  of  the  courts  of  the  United  States. 

Whenever  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  shall  have  reason  to  believe 
that  an  association  or  any  agreement  made  or  act  done  by  such  associa- 
tion is  in  restraint  of  trade  within  the  United  States  or  in  restraint  of 
the  export  trade  of  any  domestic  competitor  of  such  association,  or  that 
an  association  either  in  the  United  States  or  elsewhere  has  entered  into 
any  agreement,  understanding,  or  conspiracy,  or  done  any  act  which 
artifically  or  intentionally  enhances  or  depresses  prices  within  the 
United  States  of  commodities  of  the  class  exported  by  such  association, 
or  which  substantially  lessens  competition  within  the  United  States  or 
otherwise  restrains  trade  therein,  it  shall  summon  such  association,  its 
officers,  and  agents  to  appear  before  it,  and  thereafter  conduct  an 
investigation  into  the  alleged  violations  of  law.  Upon  investigation, 
if  it  shall  conclude  that  the  law  has  been  violated,  it  may  make  to  such 
association  recommendations  for  the  readjustment  of  its  business,  ill 
order  that  it  may  thereafter  maintain  its  organization  and  manage- 
ment and  conduct  its  business  in  accordance  with  law.  If  such  asso- 
ciation fails  to  comply  with  the  recormnendations  of  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission,  said  commission  shall  refer  its  findings  and  recommenda- 
tions to  the  Attorney  General  of  the  United  States  for  such  action 
thereon  as  he  may  deem  proper. 

For  the  purpose  of  enforcing  these  provisions  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission  shall  have  all  the  powers,  so  far  as  applicable,  given  it  in 
"An  act  to  create  a  Federal  Trade  Commission,  to  define  its  powers  and 
duties,  and  for  other  purposes." 

Approved,  April  10, 1918. 

Wilson  Tariff  Act  Antitrust  Amendments  Not  Modified  by  thb 

Export  Trade  Act 

Sections  73,  76,  and  77  of  the  Wilson  Tariff  Act,  "An  act  to  reduce 
taxation,  to  provide  revenue  for  the  Government,  and  for  other  pur- 
poses," of  August  27,  1894,  as  amended  February  12,  1913,  reads  as 
follows : 

Sec.  73.  That  every  combination,  conspiracy,  trust,  agreement,  or  contract 
is  hereby  declared  to  be  contrary  to  public  policy,  illegal,  and  void  when  the 
same  is  made  by  or  between  two  or  more  persons  or  corporations  either  of  whom, 
as  agent  or  principal,  is  engaged  in  importing  any  article  from  any  foreign 
country  into  the  United  States,  and  when  such  combination,  conspiracy,  trust, 
agreement,  or  contract  is  intended  to  operate  in  restraint  of  lawful  trade,  or 
free  competition  in  lawful  trade  or  commerce,  or  to  increase  the  market  price 
in  any  part  of  the  United  States  of  any  article  or  articles  imported  or  intended 
to  be  imported  into  the  United  States,  or  of  any  manufacture  into  which  such 


250  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 

imported  article  enters  or  is  intended  to  enter.  Every  person  who  is  or  shall 
hereafter  be  engaged  in  the  importation  of  goods  or  any  commodity  from  any 
foreign  country  in  violation  of  this  section  of  this  Act,  or  who  shall  combine  or 
conspire  with  another  to  violate  the  same,  is  guilty  of  a  misdemeanor,  and  on 
conviction  thereof  in  any  court  of  the  United  States  such  person  shall  be  lined 
in  a  sum  not  less  than  one  hundred  dollars  and  not  exceeding  five  thousand 
dollars,  and  shall  be  further  punished  by  imprisonment,  in  the  discretion  of 
the  court,  for  a  term  not  less  than  three  months  nor  exceeding  twelve  months. 

Sec.  76.  That  any  property  owned  under  any  contract  or  by  any  combination, 
or  pursuant  to  any  conspiracy,  and  being  the  subject  thereof  mentioned  in  sec- 
tion seventy-three  of  this  Act,  imported  into  and  being  within  the  United  States 
or  being  in  the  course  of  transportation  from  one  State  to  another,  or  to  or  from 
a  Territory  or  the  District  of  Columbia,  shall  be  forfeited  to  the  United  States, 
and  may  be  seized  and  condemned  by  like  proceedings  as  those  provided  by  law 
for  the  forfeiture,  seizure,  and  condemnation  of  property  imported  into  the 
United  States  contrary  to  law. 

Sec.  77.  That  any  person  whO'  shall  be  injured  in  his  busiress  or  property  by 
any  other  person  or  corporation  by  reason  of  anything  forbidden  or  declared  to 
be  unlawful  by  this  Act  may  sue  therefor  in  any  circuit  court  of  the  United 
States  in  the  district  in  which  the  defendant  resides  or  is  found,  without  respect 
to  the  amount  in  controversy,  and  shall  recover  threefold  the  damages  by  him 
sustained,  and  the  costs  of  suit,  including  a  reasonable  attorney's  fee. 

Section  6  (h)  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act  (Foreign 
Investigations) : 

Sec.  6.  That  the  Commission  shall  also  have  power — 

(h)  To  investigate  from  time  to  time  trade  conditions  in  and  with  foreign 
countries  where  associations,  combinations,  or  practices  of  manufacturers,  mer- 
chants, or  traders,  or  other  conditions  may.  affect  the  foreign  trade  of  the  United 
States,  and  to  report  to  Congress  thereon,  with  such  recommendations  as  it 
deems  advisable. 


EXHIBIT  7 

[Federal  Trade  Commission,  Washington,  Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  2] 

PRACTICE  AND  PROCEDURE  UNDER  THE  EXPORT 
TRADE  ACT  (WEBB-POMERENE  LAW),  1935 

Federal  Trade  Commission 

EwiN  L.  Davis,  Chairman;  Charles  H.  M^vech,  Vice  Chairman;  William  A. 
Ayres  ;  Garland  S.  Ferguson,  Jr.;  Robest  E.  Freer;  Otis  B.  Johnson, 
Secretary. 

(This  pamphlet  is  a  revision  of  the  Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  1, 
published  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  in  1919.  Prepared  by  the 
Export  Trade  Section  of  the  Legal  Division,  Ellen  L.  Love,  Chief, 
October  1935.) 


Index 


Purpose  of  the  law. 

Provisions  of  the  act. 

Filing  of  papers  with  the  Commission. 

Webb  law  organization  and  operation. 

Advantages    obtained    by    Webb    law 

groups. 
Products  exported. 
Associations    formed    under    the    law, 

1918-35. 


First-report  form. 

The  Export  Trade  Act. 

Sections   5  and   6    (h),   Federal   Trade 

Commission  Act. 
Section  7  of  the  Clayton  Act. 
Sections   1,   2,   and  3  of  the  Sherman 

Act. 
Sections  73,  76,  and  77  of  the  Wilson 

Tariff  Act. 


(V) 
PUEPOSE   or   THE    LAW 

The  Export  Trade  Act,  passed  on  April  10,  1918,^  is  entitled  "An 
act  to  promote  export  trade  and  for  other  purposes."  It  was  the  re- 
sult of  an  inquiry  made  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  upon 
which  report  was  made  to  Congress  in  1916.^  Hearings  were  con- 
ducted by  the  Commission  throughout  the  United  States,  attended  by 
industrialists  and  exporters  interested  in  the  proposed  legislation. 
The  Commission  recommended  to  Congress  the  passage  of  a  law 
which  should  grant  exemption  from  the  antitrust  laws  to  export  com- 
bines, with  proper  safeguards  to  domestic  business,  in  order  to  facili- 
tate the  movement  of  American  goods  to  foreign  countries,  to  serve  as 
an  encouragement  to  exporters,  and  to  enable  them  to  compete  suc- 
cessfully in  foreign  markets  with  selling  combinations  of  other 
countries. 

Bills  were  introduced  in  Congress  in  1916  and  1917  by  Senator 
Atlee  Pomerene  and  Congressman  Edwin  Y.  Webb,  and  hearings 


1  40  Stat.  516.      See  p.  14  of  this  report. 

-  Report    on    Corporation    in   American    Export    Trade,    1916,    2    vols, 
hausted). 


(supply  now  ex- 
251 


252  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEOR 

conducted  by  the  Senate  Committee  on  Interstate  Commerce  and  the 
House  Committee  on  the  Judiciary.^  The  act  is  therefore  known 
as  the  Webb  law  or  the  Webb-Pomerene  law.  It  was  endorsed  by 
President  Wilson,  Secretary  of  Commerce  Redfield,  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission,  a  number  of  trade  associations  in  various  in- 
dustries, the  chambers  of  commerce,  the  National  Foreign  Trade 
Council,  and  the  American  Manufacturers  Export  Association. 

PROVISIONS   OF   THE  ACT 

Section  1  defines  the  terms  "export  trade,"  "trade  within  the  United 
States,"  and  "association,"  wherever  used  within  the  law.  Export 
trade  means  "solely  trade  or  commerce  in  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise 
exported,  or  in  the  course  of  being  exported  from  the  United  States 
or  any  Territory  thereof  to  any  foreign  nation"  and  shall  not  be 
deemed  to  include  the  production,  manufacture,  or  selling  for  con- 
sumption or  for  resale,  within  the  United  States  or  any  Territory 
thereof.  Association  means  "any  corporation  or  combination,  by  con- 
tract or  otherwise,  of  two  or  more  persons,  partnerships,  or  cor- 
porations." 

Sections  2  and  3  provide  exemption  from  the  antitrust  laws  to  "an 
association  entered  into  for  the  sole  purpose  of  engaging  in  export 
trade  and  actually  engaged  solely  in  such  export  trade,  or  an  agree- 
ment made  or  act  done  in  the  course  of  export  trade  by  such  associa- 
tion," with  the  provision  that  uch  association,  agreement,  or  act  shall 
not  be  in  restraint  of  trade  v  .thin  the  United  States,  or  in  restraint 
of  the  export  trade  of  any  domestic  competitor ;  and  with  the  further 
prohibition  of  any  agreement,  understanding,  conspiracy,  or  act  which 
shall  artificially  or  intentionally  enhance  or  depress  prices  within  the 
United  States,  of  commodities  of  the  class  exported  by  the  association, 
substantially  lessen  competition,  or  otherwise  restrain  trade  within 
the  United  States. 

Section  4  is  an  amendment  to  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act.* 
It  extends  the  jurisdiction  of  the  Commission  to  unfair  methods  of 
competition  used  in  export  trade  against  competitors  engaged  in  ex- 
port trade,  even  though  the  acts  constituting  such  unfair  methods 
are  done  without  the  territorial  jurisdiction  of  the  United  States. 
This  section  applies  to  any  exporter  from  the  United  States,  and  not 
specifically  to  a  Webb  law  group.  Procedure  under  this  section  is 
in  accordance  with  section  5  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act. 

Section  6  of  the  Webb  law  provides  for  the  filing  of  papers  with 
the  Federal  Trade  Commission  by  an  export  association,  and  covers 
procedure  in  case  of  violation  of  the  act.    Organization  papers,  which 

8  H.  R.  16707,  Congressman  Webb,  64th  Con?.,  1st  sess.,  1916.  H.  R.  17350,  Congress- 
man Webb,  64th  Cong.,  2d  sess.,  1916.  H.  R.  2316.  Congressman  Webb,  65th  Cong,  (same 
as  S.  634,  Senator  Pomerene),  passed  both  Houses,  signed  in  1918.  Hearings  before 
House  Committee  on  the  Judiciary,  on  H.  R.  16707,  and  copy  of  bill  and  report,  serial  48, 
64th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  July  1916,  85  pages.  Hearings  before  Senate  Committee  on  Inter- 
state Commerce,  64th  Cong.,  2d  sess.,  on  H.  E.  17350,  January  1917,  156  pages.  Report 
No.  1118,  64th  Cong.,  1st  sess..  House  Committee  on  the  Judiciary,  to  accompany  H.  R. 
17350,  August  15,  1916,  4  pages.  Report  No.  1056.  64th  Cong.,  2d  sess..  Senate  Committee 
on  Interstate  Commerce,  to  accompany  H.  R.  17350,  February  14,  1917,  4  pages.  Report 
No.  9,  65th  Cong.,  let  sess.,  to  accompany  S.  634,  Senate  Committee  on  Interstate  Com- 
merce, April  16,  1917,  4  pages.  Report  No.-  50,  65th  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  to  accompany  H.  R. 
2316,  House  Committee  on  the  Judiciary,  May  11,  1917,  10  pages.  Report  No,  109,  65th 
Cong.,  1st  sess.,  Senate  Committee  on  Interstate  Commerce,  to  accompany  H.  R.  2316, 
August  15,  1917,  4  pages. 

*38  Stat.  717,  sees.  5  and  6  (h)  on  pp.  17-19  of  this  report. 


i 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EX30N0MIC  POWEH  253 

shall  be  filed  "within  30  days  after  its  creation"  include  a  verified  first 
report,  copies  of  the  articles  or  contract  of  association,  bylaws,  and 
if  the  group  is  incorporated,  a  copy  of  its  certificate  of  incorporation. 
An  annual  report  is  required,  and  the  association  shall  also  furnish 
"such  information  as  the  Commission  may  require  as  to  its  organiza- 
tion, business,  conduct,  practices,  management,  and  relation  to  other 
associations,  corporations,  partnerships,  and  individuals."  Penalties 
are  prescribed  for  failure  to  comply  with  these  provisions.  If  the 
Commission  has  reason  to  believe  that  the  law  has  been  violated,  it 
shall  conduct  inquiries  and  make  recommendations  for  readjustment 
of  the  association's  business.  Should  an  association  fail  to  comply 
with  the  recommendations,  the  Commission  shall  refer  its  findings  and 
recommendations  to  the  Attorney  General  of  the  United  States  for 
such  action  as  he  may  deem  proper. 

For  the  purpose  of  enforcing  these  provisions,  the  Commission  shall 
have  all  the  powers,  so  far  as  applicable,  that  are  given  to  it  under 
the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act. 

No  amendments  have  been  made  to  the  act  since  its  passage  in  1918. 
In  1921  a  bill  was  introduced  to  amend  section  2,^  but  little  interest  was 
shown  and  it  was  not  voted  upon.  In  1928  a  bill  was  introduced  which 
would  have  extended  the  scope  of  the  law  to  include  import  combines,^ 
but  this  was  rejected  by  the  House  of  Representatives  and  was  not 
voted  on  in  the  Senate. 

No  case  has  arisen  in  which  an  association  has  refused  to  comply 
with  recommendations  of  the  Commission;  and  no  violations  of  law- 
have  been  referred  by  the  Commission  to  the  Attorney  General. 

FILING  OF  PAPERS  WITH  THE  COMMISSION 

The  organization  of  a  Webb  law  association,  requiring,  as  it  does, 
full  cooperation  and  agreement  of  all  of  the  member  companies, 
more  often  consumes  weeks  or  months  of  discussion  and  negotiation. 
During  that  period  the  Commission  offers  its  services,  informally,  to 
the  negotiators.  The  organization  papers,  when  finally  executed,  are 
acted  upon  by  the  full  Commission.  These  papers  include  the  first 
report  (for  which  the  Commission  supplies  blanks  ^),  the  certificate  of 
incorporation  if  it  is  incorporated,  bylaws,  membership  agreement, 
contract  forms,  w^orking  rules  or  regulations,  or  other  documents  cover- 
ing the  proposed  operation.  If  there  is  any  clause  therein  that  seems 
to  show  an  intent  to  operate  in  such  a  way  as  to  violate  the  law,  in- 
formal advice  is  given  by  the  Commission  to  that  effect,  with  an  oppor- 
tunity to  amend ;  but  there  is  no  formal  approval  or  disapproval,  and 
the  receipt  or  filing  of  the  papers  does  not  serve  as  a  permit  or  license 
to  operate  under  the  law.  Before  the  act  was  passed,  an  attempt  was 
made  to  include  an  amendment  which  would  have  provided  for  per- 
mits to  be  issued  by  the  Commission,  and  authority  to  revoke  such  a 
permit;  but  strong  objection  was  voiced  and  this  provision  was  not 
made  a  part  of  the  law.  When  the  Commission  has  received  and  filed 
the  papers  of  a  newly  organized  association,  it  issues  a  brief  news 

'S.  2GS3,  67th  Cong.,  1st  sess.  (Senator  Fletcher),  Nov.  4,  1921;  same  bill  Introduced 
as  S.   812.  6Sth  Cong.,  1st  sess.,  Dec.  10,  1923. 

<S.  2312  (Senator  Wesley  L.  Jones)  and  H.  R.  8927  (Congressman  Walter  H.  Newton) 
70th  Cong..  1st  sess. 

'  Copy  of  the  first  report  form  on  pp.  11-13  of  this  report. 


254  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

release,  announcing  the  name  and  address,  its  officers  and  members, 
and  the  commodity  to  be  exported. 

Annual  reports  as  of  January  of  each  year,  keep  the  Commission's 
records  current;  blanks  for  this  purpose  are  mailed  to  each  associa- 
tion.^ Other  information  may  be  required,  and  the  association  offices 
are  visited  from  time  to  time.  Association  records  in  the  Commission 
files  are  not  open  for  public  inspection ;  but  the  Commission's  annual 
report  to  Congress  for  each  year,  covers  a  general  statement  of  opera- 
tion during  that  period,  with  a  list  of  the  association's  filing  papers  and 
a  summary  of  the  business  transacted  by  all  of  the  groups. 

The  Commission  has  received  many  inquiries  from  the  associations 
and  others,  concerning  their  operation,  to  which  reply  has  been  made 
with  informal  advice.  As  yet  none  of  the  Commission's  inquiries 
under  section  5  have  reached  the  stage  of  formal  complaint  and  hear- 
ings, and  no  formal  orders  have  been  issued. 

WEBB  LAW  ORGANIZATION   AND  OPERATION 

In  drafting  organization  papers,  the  first  thing  to  bear  in  mind  is 
that  the  association  shall  be  engaged  solely  in  export  trade;  and  this 
does  not  include  production,  manufacture,  or  selling  for  consumption 
or  for  resale,  within  the  United  States.  The  Commission  is  sometimes 
asked  if  an  association  may  operate  mills  to  produce  the  goods  for 
export;  but  the  terms  of  the  act  would  not  seem  to  cover  such  opera- 
tion and  the  Commission  has  given  informal  advice  to  that  effect. 

Under  section  1  of  the  act,  products  may  be  exported  to  "any  for- 
eign nation."  A  number  of  associations  have  asked  if  a  Webb-law 
group  may  ship  to  Puerto  Rico,  or  to  the  Philippines.  To  this  the 
Commission  has  replied  informally  that  under  numerous  court  deci- 
sions the  insular  possessions  have  been  held  to  be  not  foreign  to  this 
country ;  they  are  therefore  not  markets  to  which  a  Webb-law  group 
may  ship.  The  status  of  the  Philippine  Islands  may  be  changed  by 
independence  at  some  later  date. 

The  law  does  not  prescribe  incorporation,  but  a  number  of  groups 
formed  under  the  act  have  become  incorporated  under  State  laws 
for  their  own  convenience.  Nor  does  the  act  require  that  an  asso- 
ciation shall  be  a  nonprofit  organization,  although  many  of  the  asso- 
ciations have  operated  on  an  expense  basis,  the  profits  accruing  to 
the  individual  members. 

Usually  a  Webb-law  group  is  formed  by  producers  or  manufac- 
turers of  the  same  products,  and  there  may  be  several  groups  in  the 
same  industry.  One  of  the  lumber-export  associations  ships  red- 
wood, and  one  walnut,  but  several  have  shipped  pine.  On  the  Pa- 
cific coast  one  group  sells  dried  fruit  packed  in  California,  and  an- 
other handles  the  same  products  packed  in  the  Oregon  district.  In 
some  cases  a  Webb-law  association  has  been  affiliated  with  more  than 
one  group.  A  petroleum  company  files  as  an  association  under  the 
law  and  is  also  a  member  of  a  larger  Webb-law  group  in  the  same 
industry;  a  similar  plan  was  at  one  time  used  by  two  of  the  phos- 
phate associations  that  combined  to  form  another  group. 

The  main  office  of  the  association  may  be  at  seaport  in  order  to 
handle  the  shipping  details,  or  it  may  be  in  the  locality  of  the  mem- 

■The  annual  report  form  is  very  similar  to  the  first  report  form,  on  pp.  11-13  of  this 
report. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR  255 

ber  mills  in  order  to  serve  as  a  convenient  meeting  place  for  agree- 
ment upon  export  policies.  Branch  offices  and  agencies  may  h& 
maintained  in  this  country  and  abroad. 

In  view  of  the  wide  variety  of  products  that  have  been  exported 
under  the  act,  the  association  agreements  have  varied  considerably,, 
each  drafted  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  particular  industry  to  be 
served.  The  three  general  types  that  have  been  used  are  (1)  that 
in  which  the  association  serves  as  a  central  selling  agent  for  all  of 
the  members,  taking  orders,  negotiating  sales,  and  handling  the  ship- 
ment of  the  goods;  (2)  that  in  which  the  association  directs  the 
exportation  of  its  members  and  retains  certain  functions  in  export 
trade,  but  the  orders  are  placed  by  agents  already  established  by  the 
members  abroad;  in  this  case  the  export  department  of  one  member 
may  handle  foreign  orders  for  several  members;  and  (3)  the  export 
company  formed  for  the  purpose  of  buying  the  members'  products 
and  reselling  them  abroad  at  terms  agreed  upon  by  the  members. 
The  first  and  second  methods  of  selling  may  be  combined,  the  mem- 
bers using  their  established  agents  for  some  markets  and  the  asso- 
ciation sales  office  for  new  markets  or  those  in  which  the  trade  is 
not  well  developed. 

An  association  may  have  more  than  one  class  of  members,  depend- 
ent upon  the  service  that  it  contracts  to  perform  for  them.  One 
association  has  a  full  membership  and  a  limited  membership; 
another  has  a  packers  division  and  a  merchants  division.  In 
addition  to  its  sales  of  products  of  the  member  companies,  some 
associations  obtain  and  sell  the  products  of  other  manufacturers  in 
order  to  meot'the  demands  of  their  foreign  customers;  for  this  pur- 
pose a  separate  department  of  sales  may  be  used.  Some  of  the 
association  agreements  cover  the  entire  export  trade  of  the  mem- 
bers, some  are  limited  to  specified  product'  ^r  certain-named  mar- 
kets. A  Webb-law  association  is  a  voluntaiy  organization  and  may 
or  may  not  include  a  large  percentage  of  the  industry. 

Some  of  the  functions  that  have  been  reported  to  the  Commission 
by  associations  now  in  operation  may  be  listed  here : 

Serving  as  export  sales  agent  for  the  member  companies,  in  all 
foreign  markets  or  in  certain  markets  to  be  agreed  upon,  for  all 
goods  exported  by  the  members  or  for  only  certain  of  their  products. 

Purchasing  the  members'  products  for  resale  in  foreign  markets^ 
under  terms  and  conditions  agreed  upon  by  the  members. 

Employing  agents  and  directing  the  agents  of  the  member  com- 
panies, maintaining  offices,  in  this  country  and  abroad,  promoting 
conferences  and  agreements  in  export  trade. 

Obtaining  and  selling  goods  of  producers  outside  of  the  associa- 
tion, in  order  to  fill  the  association's  export  orders. 

Exploitation  of  members'  products  abroad,  especially  introducing 
them  in  new  markets.  Joint  advertising  and  use  of  joint  trade-marks. 
Promoting  sales  for  the  members'  brands  and  patented  goods. 

Agreeing  upon  price  for  export,  terms  and  sales  policies  in  foreign 
markets,  and  adopting  uniform  forms  of  contracts.  In  some  cases 
only  a  minimum  price  is  agreed  upon;  in  others  members  are  free 
to  quote  price  but  agree  to  report  to  the  association  any  change  in 
price. 

Dividing  the  export  business  of  the  association  among  the  mem- 
bers in  predetermined  proportions;  for  this  purpose  a  quota  system 


256  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

may  be  agreed  upon  and  the  orders  allotted  in  accordance  therewith. 

Recording  sales  of  the  members'  products,  in  export  trade,  keep- 
ing copies  of  invoices  and  other  documents;  this  is  important  when 
a  quota  plan  is  adopted. 

Standardizing  products  for  export  and  improving  the  quality  of 
the  goods.  Maintaining  inspection  service,  employing  claims  agents, 
and  settling  disputes  over  export  sales. 

Establishing  rules  and  regulations  for  packing  and  shipping  the 
goods  in  export. 

Arranging  for  freight  rates,  cargo  space,  and  shipping  dates;  con- 
solidating the  shipments  of  the  members;  taking  out  insurance  and 
shipping  documents. 

Providing  for  storage  during  transit  and  warehousing  abroad. 

Collecting  and  disseminating  trade  information  as  to  market  con- 
ditions abroad,  foreign  credits,  stocks  available  for  export  by  the 
members,  the  exchange  situation,  tariif  requirements,  shipping  rules 
and  regulations,  foreign  laws  that  aifect  our  foreign  trade,  and  other 
data  of  value  to  American  exporters. 

ADVANTAGES   OBTAINED    BY    WEBB   LAW    GROUPS 

Advantages  obtained  from  the  various  functions  listed  above  are 
obvious.  A  centralized  agency  may  effect  economy  in  sales  cost;  it 
may  get  better  freight  rates  by  consolidating  shipments;  and  it  may 
reduce  the  shipping  expense  by  arranging  for  cargo  space,  insurance, 
and  other  details.  Cooperation  in  storage  during  transit  and  ware- 
housing abroad  are  of  especial  advantage  if  the  products  are  seasonal 
and  better  prices  may  be  obtained  when  the  goods  are  fed  into  foreign 
markets  throughout  the  year. 

Agreements  upon  price  and  terms  of  sale  are  to  the  advantage  of 
the  American  exporter  and  also  to  the  foreign  buyer  who  prefers  a 
quotation  that  does  not  fluctuate  daily.  Orders  may  be  placed  several 
months  in  advance  of  shipment;  credit  may  be  arranged  for  longer 
periods  to  meet  demands  in  foreign  markets.  An  association  may  bid 
on  and  secure  large  orders  for  shipment  over  a  long  period,  which  no 
single  member  could  handle.  In  many  cases  it  is  selling  to  combines 
or  buyers  in  large  quantities  who  prefer  to  deal  with  an  organization 
with  ample  source  of  supply. 

In  improving  the  service  to  buyers  and  the  quality  of  the  goods 
shipped,  through  standardization  and  inspection  before  shipment, 
the  associations  have  reduced  claims  of  buyers,  and  have  offered  an 
efficient  service  in  handling  disputes. 

The  association  is  in  a  position  to  obtain  and  disseminate  trade 
information,  to  handle  advertisement,  and  to  do  exploitation  work 
with  minimum  expense  to  the  members. 

So  far  as  it  was  in  operation  before  the  armistice,  the  law  was  of 
benefit  in  developing  new  markets  in  Sourh  America,  and  some  food- 
stuffs and  raw  materials  were  shipped  to  Europe  for  use  of  the  Allies. 
During  the  period  of  readjustment  after  the  World  War,  American 
exporters  found  advantages  in  cooperative  effort,  and  in  1929  and  1930 
substantial  sales  were  made.  During  the  years  of  depression,  a  number 
of  associations  have  reported  to  the  Commission  that  |heir  members 
would  be  unable  to  export  without  Webb  law  organization. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR 
PRODUCTS  EXPORTED 


257 


Products  exported  by  the  Webb  law  groups  have  been  divided  by 
the  Commission,  in  its  annual  reports,  into  five  general  classes: 

(1)  Metal  and  metal  products:  Copper,  iron  and  steel,  met^l  lath, 
zinc,  machmery  and  implements,  foundry  equipment,  locomotives  and 
railway  equipment,  electrical  apparatus,  signal  apparatus,  tools,  pipes, 
valves,  and  screws. 

(2)  Products  of  mines  and  wells:  Sulfur,  phosphate  rock,  coal  and 
coke,  petroleum  products,  carbon  black. 

(3)  Lumber  and  wood  products:  Pine,  fir,  hardwood,  redwood, 
walnut,  naval  stores,  plywood,  doors,  furniture  and  ofiice  equipment, 
wood  pipe,  shooks,  wooden  tool  handles,  clothespins. 

(4)  Foodstuffs:  Canned  milk,  meat  products,  sugar,  flour  and  other 
grain  products,  rice,  sardines,  canned  salmon,  peas,  canned  vegetables, 
and  fruit  (fresh,  dried,  and  canned). 

(5)  Other  manufactured  products :  Paper,  textiles,  rubber  products, 
abrasives,  cement,  fertilizer,  paint  and  varnish,  insecticides,  alcohol, 
tanning  materials,  soda  pulp,  soda  ash,  alkali,  other  chemicals,  cotton 
linters,  clothing,  buttons,  and  general  merchandise. 

These  broad  groupings  were  adopted  in  order  to  give  to  the  public 
information  as  to  the  kinds  of  goods  exported,  and  their  value,  with- 
out divulging  statistics  reported  by  any  one  company  or  association. 

Total  exports^  during  the  years  1920  to  1934,  inclusive,  were  as 
follows : 


Year 

Metals  and 

metal 

products 

Products  of 

mines  and 

wells 

Lumber  and 

wood 

products 

Foodstuffs 

other  manu- 
factured 
products 

Totals 

1920                  

$152,000,000 
67,  557, 000 

$8, 000, 000 
5,  556, 000 

$17,000,000 
9, 894, 000 

$8, 000, 000 
5, 839, 000 

$36,000,000 
2,334,000 

$221,000,000 
91,180,000 

1921 

1922' 

1923 

68,  227, 000 

43, 992, 000 

43, 287, 000 

56.  500. 000 

180, 000, 000 

267,  600. 000 

271.000.000 

208. 000, 000 

100, 000, 000 

21,000,000 

29, 000,  0(X> 

27, 000, 000 

10,500,000 

9, 885, 000 

14,279,000 

14,300,000 

15,200,000 

17,  50O,  000 

270.  000. 000 

31,5,T)00,000 

73.  009. 000 

56, 000, 000 

44,  000,  000 

53, 000, 000 

26, 000, 000 
32, 700, 000 
38. 000. 000 
35,  700,  000 
35,  400, 000 
28,  200,  000 
26, 000, 009 
22,  500.  OW 

32,  400, 000 
35. 300. 000 
42, 000, 000 
35. 000. 000 
53, 000. 000 
80, 40n.  000 
67.  100, 000 
40.  500.  000 

16,373,000 
18, 123. 000 
27. 934. 000 
59.000,000 
87,  900, 000 
82.  500, 000 
90, 000, 000 
75, 000, 000 
70,  100, 000 
3  J.  000. 000 
34. 000. 000 
36,  000, 000 

153,500,000 
140, 000, 000 
165,500  000 

1924 

1925 

1926    -     - 

200,  500, 000 
371  500  000 

1927 

1928 

476,  200, 000 

1929    . 

724  100  000 

1930...     .- 

661,000,000 

1931 

35,  400.  OiK)         32.  500.  000 

311,000,000 

1932  .- 

8.  000,  000 
8.  000,  000 
8,  500,  000 

24.  000.  000 
28,  0!)0,  000 
21,300,000 

144,000  000 

1933... 

1934 

143, 000, 000 
145, 800, 000 

'  Figures  for  1922  not  co^lpiled. 

The  decrease  in  the  value  of  exports  from  1931  to  1934  was  due  to 
depressed  conditions  in  foreign  markets,  including  the  lack  of  pur- 
chasing power,  uncertain  credits,  exchange  control,  import  quota  and 
license  systems,  increased  duties,  and,  in  some  cases,  total  exclusion  of 
products  theretofore  imported  from  this  country.  It  was  also  due 
to  tlie  fact  that  by  reason  of  the  very  low  prices  prevailing  ir  for- 
eign markets,  some  of  \\\^  member  companies  were  unwilling  to  ship 
and  some  of  the  ass«'cia£k»ns  suspended  price  agreements,  permitting 
members  to  sell  at  independent  prices;  the  independent  sales  were 
not  reported  or  included  in  the  Webb-law  totals  for  those  years. 

•  In  round  numbers. 


258  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

ASSOCIATIONS  FORMED  UNDER  THE  LAW,    1918-35 

The  first  groups  to  form  under  the  law  were  the  lumber  exporters, 
the  copper  and  steel  associations,  exporters  of  machinery,  railway 
equipment,  phosphate,  chemicals,  paper,  furniture,  elastic  webbing, 
and  a  number  of  exporters  of  foodstuffs  (some  of  these  for  the  pur- 
pose of  selling  grain  products  to  the  Allies).  Several  groups  were 
formed  to  handle  miscellaneous  exports  to  specific  markets,  but  this 
plan  was  not  a  success.  An  exporter  of  lumber  is  not  equipped  to 
sell  food  products  or  unrelated  goods ;  and  it  was  found  a  better  plan 
to  form  the  groups  on  the  commodity  basis  rather  than  for  regional- 
trade  development.  Passage  of  the  Capper- Volstead  Act,  granting 
antitrust  exemption  to  agricultural  cooperatives,  in  1922,  precluded 
the  formation  of  those  groups  under  the  Webb  law.  The  sulfur 
and  rubber  groups  were  formed  in  1922,  the  petroleum  associations 
in  1929,  the  textile  groups  in  1930,  and  the  electrical  association  in 
1931.     Other  important  associations  are  noted  in  the  list  below. 

In  1920  there  were  43  associations  in  operation.  Several  dropped 
out  during  the  readjustment  period,  in  1921  and  1922;  but  others 
were  formed,  and  in  1929,  1930,  and  1931  there  were  57  associations 
on  the  Commission's  list.  The  number  dropped  to  45  in  1934,  and 
44  in  1935.  Although  exportation  has  been  exceedingly  difficult  dur- 
ing the  depression,  most  of  the  associations  have  maintained  their 
organization  and  continued  to  operate  to  some  extent. 

The  following  list  includes  associations  that  have  operated  under 
the  law  during  the  years  1918  to  1935 :  ^° 

Alabama-Florida  Pitch  Pine  Export  Association,  New  Orleans 1929-33 

American  Brake  Beam  Manufacturers  Export  Association,  West  Nyack, 

N.    Y 1925-29 

American  Corn  Products  Export  Association,  New  York  City 1922-27 

American  Export  Door  Corporation,  Tacoma,  Wash 1927-30 

American  Export  Lumber  Corporation,  Philadelphia 1919-20 

American  Hardwood  Exporters,  Inc.,  New  Orleans . 1930-35 

American  Locomotive  Sales  Corporation,  New  York  City 1919-35 

American  Maize  Products  Export  Association,  Chicago 1919 

Name  changed  to  U.^.  Maize  Products  Export  Association 1920-26 

American  Milk  Products  Corporation,  New  York  City 1919-30 

Name  changed  to  General  Milk  Co.  in  1930 1930-35 

American  Paper  Exports,  Inc.,  New  York  City 1918-35 

American  Pitch  Pine  Export  Co.,  New  Orleans 1919-35 

American  Producers  Export  Corporation  of  Delaware,  New  York  City 1921-22 

American  Producers  Export  Corporation  of  New  York,  New  York  City 19^1-22 

American  Provisions  Export  Co.,  Chicago 1919-35 

American  Rice  Export  Corporation,  Crowley,  La 1927-33 

American  Soda  Pulp  Export  Association,  New  York  City 1919-35 

American  Soft  Wheat  Millers  Export  Corporation,  Washington,  D.  C 1927-34 

American  Spring  Manufacturers  Export  Association,  New  York  City 1923-35 

American  Surface  Abrasive  Export  Corporation,  New  York  City 1923-31 

(Some  of  the  members  now  in  Durex  Abrasive  Corporation.) 

American  Tanning  Materials  Corporation,  New  York  City 1919-:*3 

American  Textile  Machinery  Corporation,  Boston 1919-2.> 

American  Textile  Trading  Co.,  New  York  City 1930-34 

American  Tire  Ma:nufacturers  Export  Association,  New  York  City 1923-35 

American  Webbing  Manufacturers  Export  Association,  New  York  City 1919^32 

Association  Button  Exporters  of  America,  Inc.,  New  York  City 1921-33 

"This  list  does  not  include  a  number  of  companies  that  filed  p>ipers  under  misappre- 
hension during  the  first  year  of  operation  ;  they  were  foufid  to  be  engaged  in  business 
other  than  exporting,  and  were  dropped  from  tlie  Commission's  register. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  259 

Atlantic  &  Gulf  Export  Co.,  Jacksonville,  Fla 1921 

Automatic  Pearl  Button  Export  Co.,  Inc.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 1921-29 

California  Dried  Fruit  Export  Association,  San  Francisco 1925-35 

California  Sardine  Export  Association,  San  Francisco 1928-30 

Canned  Foods  Export  Corporation,  Washington,  D.  C 1919-23 

Carbon  Black  Export  Association,  Inc.,  New  York  City 1929-33 

Some  of  the  members  now  in  the  Carbon  Black  Export,  Inc.,  New 

York  City 1933-S5 

Carolina  Wood  Export  Corporation,  Norfolk,  Va ; 1919-32 

Cement  Export  Co.,  The,  Philadelphia  and  New  York  City 1919-35 

Chalmers  (Harvey)  &  Son  Export  Corporation,  Amsterdam,  N.  Y 1921-31 

Clandere  Export  Corporation.  New  York  City 1921-23 

Consolidated  Steel  Corporation,  New  York  City 1919-23 

( Some  members  now  in  Steel  Export  Association  of  U.  S. ) 

Copper  Export  Association,  New  York  City 1919-33 

Copper  Exporters.  Inc.,  New  York  City 1926-35 

Davenport  Pearl  Button  Export  Co.,  Davenport,  Iowa 1921-31 

Delta  Export  Lumber  Corporation,  Memphis,  Tenn 1922-26 

Douglas  Fir  Exploitation  &  Export  Co.,  Seattle 1918-35 

Durex  Abrasives  Corporation,  New  York  City 1920-35 

Electrical  Apparatus  Export  Association.  New  York  Citv 1931-35 

Export  Clothes  Pin  Association  of  America,  Inc..  New  York  City 1919-30 

Export  Petroleum  Association,  Inc..  New  York  City 1929-35 

Export  Screw  Association  of  the  United  States.,  Providence.  R.  I 1926-35 

Exporters  of  Wood  Products,  Inc..  New  York  City l92f4-29 

( Some  members  now  in  Shook  Exporters  Association. ) 

Exporting  Rye  Millers  Association,  Minneapolis,  Minn 1920 

Florida  Hard  Rock  Phosphate  Export  Association,  Savannah,  6a 1919-35 

Florida  Pebble  Phosphate  Export  Association,  New  York  City 1919-33 

(Consolidated  with  Phosphate  Export  Association  in  1933.) 

Florida  Pine  Export  Association,  Jacksonville.  Fla 1930-31 

Foundry  Equipment  Export  Coi'poration,  Philadelphia 1919-21 

General  Alcghol  Export  Corporation,  New  York  City 1919-24 

General  Milk  Co.,  Inc..  New  York  Citv 1930-35 

(Was  American  Milk  Products  Corporation,  1919i-30.) 

Goodyear  Tire  &  Rubber  Export  Co..  The.  Akron,  Ohio 1922-35 

Grain  Products  Export  .\ssociation,  New  York  City 1922-27 

Grand  Rapids  Furniture  Expoi't  Association,  Grand  Rapids,  Mich 1920-27 

Grapefruit  Distributors,  Inc.,  Davenport,  Fla 1930-35 

Gulf  Pitch  Pine  Export  Association.  New  Orleans 1920-33 

Hawkeye  Pearl  Button  Export  Co.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 1921-35 

Inter-America  Exporters,  Inc.,  New  York  City 1935 

International  Steel  Corporation,  New  York  City l'.>lS-23 

Locomotive  Export  Association,  New  York  City 1920-29 

MfKee  P>utton  Export  Co.,  Muscatine.  Iowa 1921-25 

Mpfal  L.itb  Export  Association,  The,  New  York  City 192fKS5 

Millers  Export  Association,  Inc.,  Chicago,  111 1919-22 

Mississippi  Valley  Trading  &  Navigation  Co.,  St.  Louis,  Mo 1920-23 

Namusa  Corporation.  New  York  City —  1919-22 

Naval  Stores  Export  Corporation,  Savannah,  Ga 192.'>-30 

Nogales  Garbanzo  Association.  Nogales,  Ariz 1921-22 

Northwest  Dried  Fruit  Export  Association,  Portland,  Oreg 1927-.35 

Northwest  Lumber  Exporters  A'^sociation,  Seattle,  Wash 1929-31 

(Some  members  joined  Douglas  Fir  Association  &  Export  Co.) 

Pacific  Flour  Export  Co.,  Seattle.  Wash 1924-35 

Pacific  Forest  Industx-ies,  Tacoma.  Wa.sh 1935 

Pan  American  Trading  Co..  New  York  City 1919^27 

Pennsylvania   Millers  Export  Association.  Philadelphia 1919-20 

Phosphate  Export  Association,  New  York  City 1919-35 

Pioneer  Peari  Button  Export  Corporation,  Poughkeepsie,  N.  Y 1922-29 

PIl)o  Fittinss  &  Valve  Export  A=;sociation,  The,  Philadelphia 1919-35 

Producers  Linter  Export  Co..  New  Orleans 1924-32 

Redwood   Export   Co..    San    Francisco 1918-35 

Rice  Export  Co.,  Lake  Charles,  La 1929-31 

(Some  members  joined  American  Rice  Export  Corporation.) 
Rubber  Export  Association,  The,  Akron,  Ohio 1922-35 

2.^7769— 41— No.  6 18 


2g0  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEK 

Salmon  Export  Corporation,  Seattle 1926-30 

Shook  Exporters  Association,  New  York  City 1932-35 

Signal  Export  Association,  New  York  City 1931-35 

South  American  Fruit  Exporters,  Inc.,  New  York  City 1927-31 

Standard  Oil  Export  Corporation,  New  York  City 1929-35 

Steel  Export  Association  of  America,  The,  New  York  City 1928-35 

Sugar  Export  Corporation,  New  York  City 1922-35 

Sulphur  Export  Corporation,  New  York  City 1922-35 

Textile  Alliance  Export  Corporation,  New  York  City 1919 

(Name  changed  to  Textile  Manufacturers  Alliance  in  1919.) 

Textile  Export  AssQCiation  of  the  U.  S.,  New  York  City 1930-35 

Textile  Manufacturers  Alliance,  Inc.,  New  York  City 1919-20 

United  Export  Lumber  Association,  Seattle 1931-32 

United  Paint  &  Varnish  Export  Co.,  Cleveland 1920-29 

U.  S.  Alkali  Export  Association,  Inc.,  New  York  City 1919-35 

U.  S.  Button  Export  Co.,  Muscatine,  Iowa 1921-28 

U.  S.  Forest  Products  Co.,  Kansas  City,  Mo 1919-22 

U.  S.  Handle  Export  Co.,  The,  Piqua.  Ohio 1919-35 

U.  S.  Maize  Products  Export  Association,  Inc.,  Wilkes-Barre,  Pa 1920-26 

(Operated     as     American     Maize    Products     Export    Association, 
1919-20. ) 

U.  S.  Office  Equipment  Export  Association,  New  York  City 1918-23 

U.  S.  Provision  Export  Corporation,  Chicago 1919-22 

Walnut  Export  Sales  Co.,  Inc.,  Kansas  City,  Kans 1918-35 

Walworth  International  Co.,  New  York  City 1920-35 

Western  Plywood  Export  Co.,  Tacoma,  Wash 1927-35 

Wisconin  Canners  Export  Association,  Manitowoc,  Wis 1920-29 

Wood  Naval"  Stores  Export  Association,  Wilmington,  Del 1935 

Wood  Pipe  Export  Co.,  Seattle 1920-23 

Zinc  Export  Association,  New  York  City 1925-34 


EXHIBIT  8 

[Federal  Trade  Commission] 

FOREIGN  TRADE  WORK 

ExcraiPTS  From  Annual  Report  of  the  Federal  I'rade  Commission 
FOR  THE  Fiscal  Year  Ended  June  30,  1937 

No\tjmbbr  24,  1937. 

FEDBaiAL  Trade  Commission 

William  A.  Atees,  Chairman;  Garland  S.  Ferguson,  Jr.,  Vice  Chairman; 
Chaeles  H.  March  ;  Ewin  L.  Davis;  Robekt  E.  Freek;  Otis  B.  Johnson, 
Secretary. 

Foreign  trade  work  of  the  Commission  includes  administration  of 
the  Export  Trade  Act,  commonly  known  as  the  Webb-Pomerene 
law,  and  inquiries  made  under  section  6  (h)  of  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission  Act,  which  empowers  the  Commission  to  investigate  trade 
conditions  in  and  with  foreign  countries.  This  work  is  handled  by  the 
export  trade  section  of  the  Legal  Division. 

THE   EXPORT  TRADE   ACT 

The  Export  Trade  Act,  passed  by  Congress  in  1918,  grants  exemp- 
tion from  the  antitrust  laws  to  export  combines  or  associations,  which 
are  required  to  file  with  the  Commission  copies  of  their  organization 
papei"s,  annual  reports,  and  such  other  information  as  the  Commis- 
sion may  require  as  to  their  organization,  business,  conduct,  practices, 
management,  and  relation  to  other  associations,  corporations,  partner- 
ships, and  individuals.  In  case  of  violation  of  the  law,  the  Commis- 
sion may  conduct  inquiries  and  make  recommendations  for  readjust- 
ment of  a  business.  Should  an  association  fail  to  comply  with  the 
recommendations,  the  matter  may  be  referred  to  the  Attorney  General 
for  further  action. 

Such  an  association  must  be  solely  engaged  in  export  trade;  and  the 
law  provides  that  it  shall  not  restrain  the  export  trade  of  a  domestic 
competitor;  artificially  or  intentionally  enhance  or  depress  prices 
within  the  United  States  of  commodities  of  the  class  exp-orted  by  the 
association;  substantially  lessen  competition  or  otherwise  restrain 
trade  within  the  United  States. 

EXPORTS    increase   IN    19  3G 

Reports  of  associations  filing  papers  under  tlie  Export  Trade  Act 
show  an  upsvring  in  exports  for  the  yeaf  1936,  due  to  improved  con- 
ditions abroad,  a  lessening  of  trade  restrictions  in  foreign  countries, 

261 


262 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEJR 


and  strong  association  effort  to  increase  sales  in  spite  of  foreign  com- 
petition. 

Total  exports  for  that  year  amounted  to  $149,296,525,  and  exceeded 
by  approximately  $11,600,000  the  associations'  exports  in  1935,  in  spite 
of  the  fact  that  two  of  the  largest  groups,  exporting  petroleum,  were 
dissolved  in  1936. 


Association  exports  for  the  years  1935  and  1936 


1935 


1936 


Metals  and  metal  products,  including  iron  and  steel  products,  copper,  metal 
lath,  machinery,  railway  equipment,  pipes  and  valves,  and  electrical 
equipment 

Products  of  mines  and  wells:  Crude  sulfur,  phosphate  rock,  petroleum,  and 
carbon  black 

Lumber  and  wood  products:  Pine,  fir,  redwood,  walnut,  hardwood,  plywood, 
barrel  and  box  shooks,  tool  handles,  and  wood  naval  stores 

Foodstuffs,  such  as  milk,  meat,  sugar,  flour,  and  fruit 

Other  manufactured  goods:  Rubber,  paper,  textiles,  glass,  cement,  abrasives, 
and  chemicals 

Total 


$20,  250, 000 

55, 875,  000 

9,  450, 000 
16,  500,  000 

35,  610, 000 


137, 085, 000 


$40,  507,  335 
40,  780,  283 


8,  533,  374 
21,250,433 


38,  225,  lOO 


149,  296.  525 


FORTY-FIVE  ASSOCIATIONS   OPERATING   UNDER   THE   EXPORT  TRADE   ACT 

New  associations  organized  under  the  Export  Trade  Act  during  the 
fiscal  year  ended  June  30,  1937,  were :  California  Alkali  Export  Asso- 
ciation, comprising  three  member  companies  in  California,  with  head- 
quarters in  Los  Angeles ;  Pacific  Fresh  Fruit  Export  Association,  com- 
prising nine  member  companies  in  California  and  Washington,  with 
headquarters  in  San  Francisco ;  and  Scrap  Export  Associates  of  Amer- 
ica, comprising  three  member  companies  in  New  York  and  Pennsyl- 
vania, with  headquarters  in  New  York  City. 

At  the  end  of  the  fiscal  year,  45  export  trade  associations  were  on 
file  with  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  as  follows : 


American  Box  Shook  Export  Associa- 
tion, Barr  Building,  Washington,  D.  C. 

American  Hardwood  Exporters,  Inc., 
Queen  and  Crescent  Building,  New 
Orleans. 

American  Locomotive  Sales  Corpora- 
tion. 30  Church  Street,  New  York. 

American  Paper  Exports,  Inc.,  75  West 
Street,   New  York. 

American  Provisions  Export  Co.,  80  East 
Jackson  Boulevard,  Chicago. 

American  Soda  Pulp  Export  Association, 
230  Park  Avenue,  New  York. 

American  Spring  Manufacturers  Export 
Association,  30  Church  Street,  New 
York. 

American  Tire  Manufacturers  Export 
Association,  30  Church  Street,  New 
York. 

California  Alkali  Export  Association, 
523  West   Sixth  Street,  Los  Angeles. 

California  Dried  Fruit  Export  Associa- 
tion, 1  Drumm  Street,  San  Francisco. 

California  Prune  Export  Association,  1 
Drumm  Street,  San  Francisco. 

Carbon  Black  Export,  Inc.,  500  Fifth 
Avenue,   New  York. 


Cement  Export  Co.,  Inc.,  150  Broadway, 
New  York   City. 

Copper  Exporters,  Inc.,  50  Broadway, 
New  York. 

Douglas  Fir  Export  Co.,  Henry  Build- 
ing,  Seattle,  Wash. 

Durex  Abrasives  Corporation,  63  Wall 
Street,   New   York. 

Electrical  Apparatus  Export  Associa- 
tion, 70  Pine  Street,  New  York. 

Export  Screw  Association  of  the  United 
States,  23  Acorn  Street,  Providence, 
R.  I. 

Florida  Hard  Rock  Phosphate  Export 
Association,  Savannah  Bank  and 
Trust  Building,  Savannah,  Ga. 

General  Milk  Co.,  Inc.,  19  Rector  Street, 
New  York. 

Goodyear  Tire  &  Rubber  Export  Co., 
1144  East  Market  Street,  Akron, 
Ohio. 

Grapefruit  Distributors.  Inc.,  Daven- 
I)ort,   Fla. 

Inter-America  Exporters,  Inc.;  11  Broad- 
way,  New   York. 

Metal  Lath  Export  Association,  47  West 
Thirty-fourth  Street,  New  York. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH  263 

Northwest  Dried  Fruit  Export  Associa-  Signal  Export  Association,   74  Trinity 

tion,  Title  and  Trust  Building,  Port-  Place,   New  York. 

land,   Oreg.  Steel  Export  Association  of  America,  75 

Pacific  Flour  Export  Co.,  care  of  Fisher  West  Street,  New  York. 

Flouring  Mills  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash.  Sugar    Export    Corporation,    120   Wall 

Pacific      Forest      Industries,      Tacoma  Street,  New  York. 

Building,  Tacoma,  Wash.  Sulphur  Export  Corporation,  420  Lex- 
Pacific  Fresh  Fruit  Export  Association,  ington  Avenue,  New  York. 

451  California  Street,  San  Francisco.  Textile     Export     Association     of     the 

Phosphate  Export  Association,  393  Sev-  United  States,  40  Worth  Street,  New 

enth  Avenue,  New  York.  York. 
Pipe  Fittings  &  Valve  Export  Associa-  United   States  Alkali  Export   Associa- 
tion, 1421  Chestnut  Street,  Philadel-  tion.  Inc.,  11  Broad way,^  New  York. 

phia.  United  States  Handle  Export  Co.,  Piqua, 

Plate  Glass  Export  Corporation,  Grant  Ohio. 

Building,   Pittsburgh.  Walnut  Export  Sales  Co.,  Inc.,  Twelfth 

Redwood  Export  Co.,  405  Montgomery  Street  and  Kaw  River,  Kansas  City, 

Street,  San  Francisco.  Kans. 

Rubber   Export   Association,   19    Good-  Walworth    International    Co.,   60   East 

year  Avenue,  Akron,  Ohio.  Forty-second  Street,  New  York. 

Scrap   Export   Associates   of   America,  Wood  Naval  Stores  Export  Association, 

350  Fifth  Avenue,  New  York.  1220  Delaware  Trust  Building,  Wil- 

Shook  Exporters  Association,  Stahlman  mington,  Del. 

Building,  Nashville,  Ten. 

ADVANTAGES  OBTAINED  BY  EXPORTERS  IN  1936 

Associations  operating  under  the  law  represent  mills,  mines,  fac- 
tories, and  processing  plants  in  all  parts  of  the  country.  Shipments 
are  made  to  all  parts  of  the  world. 

The  export  association  presents  a  united  front  to  foreign  competi- 
tion; it  concentrates  and  simplifies  the  problem  of  sales,  makes  for 
economy  in  operation,  and  generally  builds  up  the  prestige  of  Ameri- 
can goods  abroad.  An  association  may  adopt  uniform  sales  terms  as  to 
price,  credit,  shipping  dates,  packing  requirements,  and  other  details 
of  shipment.  Complaints  of  foreign  buyers  against  American  ship- 
pers may  be  reduced  through  a  centralized  inspection  service  and  an 
adjustment  department.    An  arbitration  board  lessens  legal  expense. 

Cooperative  purchase  of  cargo  space  was  especially  helpful  during 
the  maritime  strike  tie-up  of  1936.  The  pooling  of  orders  makes  it 
possible  to  complete  large  sales  contracts  over  a  longer  period  of  ship- 
ment than  could  be  handled  by  one  company  alone.  Standardization 
of  products  and  improvement  in  quality,  have  been  effected  through 
cooperative  effort.  Foreign  buyers  show  more  confidence  in  dealing 
with  a  large  group  of  exporters  than  with  a  single  company  less 
known  to  the  trade.  The  association  is  in  a  position  to  obtain  current 
information  for  dissemination  among  the  members  as  to  market  condi- 
tions abroad,  tariffs,  shipping  requirements,  tax  regulations,  and 
exchange  restrictions. 

Exports  were  somewhat  lessened  in  1936  by  labor  disturbances, 
notably  the  maritime  strike  on  the  west  coast  which  delayed  shipments 
and  resulted  in  some  cancelation  of  orders.  There  are  still  high  duties 
and  import  quota  plans  in  some  countries  abroad,  although  associa- 
tions report  that  reciprocal-tariff  agreements  negotiated  by  the  United 
States  have  served  to  lessen  these  restrictions.  Revaluation  of  gold- 
block  currencies  at  lower  levels  gave  foreign  competitors  an  ad- 
vantage. The  policy  of  some  countries  to  increase  production  to  the 
point  of  becoming  self-sustaining  in  time  of  war  has  led  to  changes 


264  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

in  producing  areas.  Manufacturing  plants  have  been  built  in  the 
Orient,  much  effort  has  been  spent  in  the  development  of  substitute 
products  in  Europe,  and  the  cultivation  of  grain  and  other  foodstuffs 
has  been  eiMjouraged  abroad.  These  changes  must  be  met  and  new 
markets  developed  to  take  the  place  of  old.  The  Webb-Pomerene  law 
offers  a  method  under  which  the  expense  and  effort  of  developing  new 
markets  may  be  divided  among  a  number  of  exporters,  for  the  bene- 
fit of  all. 

TRUST   LAWS   AND   UNFAIR    COMPETITION    IN    FOREIGN    COUNTRIES 

In  accordance  with  section  6  (h)  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission 
Act,  directing  inquiries  as  to  trade  conditions  in  and  with  foreign 
countries,  the  Commission  notes  the  following  measures  involving 
trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  abroad : 

Argentina. — Recent  legislation  authorized  Government  purchase 
and  destruction  of  vineyards  in  order  to  reduce  the  production  of  wine 
grapes.  An  JExecutive  decree  of  August  7, 1936,  provided  for  appoint- 
ment of  a  commission  to  study  plans  and  present  recommendations  for 
agricultural  laws  and  policies.  A  national  wool  institute  was  created 
by  decree  of  June  10,  1936,  to  promote  production  and  regulate  prices. 
Under  an  Executive  decree  on  July  20,  1936,  all  imports  and  exports 
of  petroleum  must  be  handled  by  a  Government-controlled  agency  with 
authority  to  allocate  markets  and  to  operate  a  monopoly  for  sale  of 
petroleum  in  the  federal  capital. 

Australia. — Decision  of  the  Privy  Council  at  London  in  July  1936, 
invalidating  the  Dried  Fruit  Control  Act,  seriously  affected  the  Com- 
monwealth plans  for  production  control.  Government  aid  to  agri- 
culture had  been  effected  for  some  years  through  bounties  and  market- 
ing schemes.  Domestic  prices  were  maintained  above  export  prices, 
and  the  difference  paid  to  exporters,  control  having  been  adminis- 
tered by  Commonwealth  export  control  boards  working  in  cooperation 
with  control  boards  in  the  producing  states.  The  Privy  Council  held 
the  dried  fruit  control  to  be  in  violation  of  section  92  of  the  Com- 
monwealth Constitution,  which  insures  free  trade  between  the  Aus- 
tralian states  {James  v.  Commomoealth  of  Australia).  Thereafter 
amendments  were  proposed  to  make  section  92  inapplicable  to  mar- 
keting laws,  and  to  permit  laws  regulating  aviation,  the  Common- 
wealth Air  Navigation  Act  having  been  held  invalid  by  the  High 
"Court  of  Australia.  But  the  proposed  constitutio!idl  amendments 
were  rejected  by  the  states  in  1937.  Section  7  of  die  Industries 
Preservation  Act,  which  provides  for  freight-dumpnig  duties,  was 
amended  December  7,  1936. 

Austria. — Increased  prices  in  raw  materials  and  semifinished  goods 
have  led  to  an  increase  in  retail  prices,  and  a  demand  for  govern- 
mental price  fixing  for  necessaries.  A  price  commissary  has  been  ap- 
pointed to  receive  claims  and  provide  official  hearings  for  disputes 
between  producers,  manufacturers,  dealers,  and  consumers. 

Bolivia. — The  price  and  profits  control  decree  of  June  20,  1936, 
provided  that  establishments  dealing  in  articles  of  basic  necessity  be 
limited  to  a  maximum  profit  of  12  percent,  and  other  firms  to  a  maxi- 
mum commercial  profit  of  20  percent.  Stocks  will  be  inventoried, 
actual  costs  of  prime  necessities  computed,  and  selling  prices  fixed  by 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR  265 

inspectors  of  the  permanent  fiscal  commission.  A  decree  dated  August 
20,  1936,  required  that  any  inhabitant  who  participates  in  any  way 
in  the  production  and  distribution  of  wealth  be  required  to  join  a 
syndicate  operating  under  a  national  bureau  of  syndicates.  An 
Executive  decree  of  December  21,  1936,  created  a  Government  petro- 
leum monopoly. 

Canada. — Judgments  were  rendered  by  the  Privy  Council  in 
London,  January  28,  1937,  on  a  number  of  Canadian  laws.  The 
Farmers  Creditors  Arrangement  Act  was  upheld  by  the  council,  as 
was  section  498A  of  the  criminal  code  which  provides  penalties  for 
the  granting  of  discriminatory  discounts,  rebates,  and  allowances. 
The  Dominion  Trade  and  Industry  Commission  Act  was  upheld  in 
part,  but  no  appeal  was  taken  from  decision  of  the  Supreme  Court 
of  Canada  which  had  held  invalid  section  14  providing  for  price  reg- 
ulation and  production  control  by  the  Dominion.  Government.  The 
Natural  Products  Marketing  Act  which  had  provided  for  agricul- 
tural agreements,  the  Employment  and  Social  Insurance  Act,  the 
Minimum  Wages  Act,  Limitation  of  Hours  of  Work  Act,  and  the 
Weekly-Day-oi-Rest-in-Seven  Act,  w^ere  held  invalid,  and  beyond 
the  power  of  the  Dominion  Parliament  under  the  British  North 
America  Act  which  reserves  to  the  provinces  control  of  trade  and 
industry  within  their  borders. 

The  Combines  Investigation  Act,  1923,  was  amended  on  April  10, 
1937;  the  law  will  now  be  administered  by  a  commissioner  under  the 
Minister  of  Labor.  A  report  was  made  by  a  royal  commission,  dated 
February  3,  1937,  on  importation  and  distribution  of  anthracite 
coal  in  the  Dominion.  The  antidumping  provisions  of  the  Customs 
Tariff  Act  were  amended  in  1937. 

China. — In  December,  1936,  a  national  foodstuffs  distribution  and 
transportation  bureau  was  opened  at  Shanghai,  to  put  foodstuffs 
under  national  control  and  to  effect  an  adjustment  between  supply 
and  demand  in  order  to  prevent  local  shortage  and  speculation  in 
price. 

Colombia. — Under  an  act  approved  in  1936,  the  Government  may 
acquire  utilities  that  are  considered  of  public  and  social  interest.  A 
new  land-ownership  law  effective  on  December  30,  1936.  provided 
that  all  rural  lands  shall  revert  to  the  state  unless  continuous  pos- 
session or  economic  exploitation  is  shown  for  10  years. 

Czechoslovakia. — In  order  to  forestall  an  increase  in  prices  after 
devaluation  of  the  crown,  a  decree  issued  in  October  1936  directed 
local  authorities  to  watch  the  prices  of  daily  necessities,  raw  ma- 
terials, intermediates,  and  other  production  materials,  and  to  report 
to  a  newly  created  price  advisory  board  in  case  of  unwarranted 
price  increase,  speculative  buying,  curtailment  of  production,  and 
any  measures  tending  to  increase  prices  or  result  in  profiteering. 

A  decree  dated  July  23,  1936,  provided  for  organization  of  all 
textile  producers  into  a  syndicate,  under  regulation  of  a  board  author- 
ized to  issue  licenses  and  determine  problems  of  production  and  dis- 
tribution. A  decree  dated  July  8,  1936,  amended  the  national  de- 
fense law  of  May  13,  1936,  defining  war  industries  and  providing 
strict  con,trol  for  all  of  the  industries  and  trades  named  therein. 
The  wheat  monopoly  law  was  extended  to  June  30,  1940.  Compulsory 
labor  exchanges  were  introduced  in  October  1936;  strikes  and  lock- 
outs are  not  permitted. 


266  CONOENTKATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEB 

France. — The  Price  Control  Act,  passed  on  August  19,  1936,  pro- 
vided for  governmental  committees  to  survey  wholesale  and  retail 
prices,  determine  a  normal  spread  between  cost  and  sales  price,  and 
to  prohibit  unjustified  increase  in  price.  The  Monetary  Act  of 
October  3,  1936,  included  a  provision  against  alteration  of  the  prica 
level.  A  decree  of  November  25  provided  for  a  bureau  to  make  in- 
quiries and  recommendations  toward  a  reduction  in  production 
costs.  A  law  passed  February  15,  1937,  declared  illegal  all  price  in- 
creases on  foodstuffs,  merchandise,  and  services  of  prime  necessity, 
above  the  level  of  August  1,  1936,  unless  justified  by  a  rise  in  the 
price  of  raw  materials  or  an  increase  in  service  charges.  A  national 
price-surveillance  committee  was  provided  to  fix  prices,  in  agreement 
with  wholesalers  and  retailers. 

A  decree  issued  on  July  1,  1937,  forbade  an  increase  in  prices  or 
service  charges  above  those  in  effect  on  June  28,  1937. 

The  Coal  Act,  passed  on  August  18,  1936,  empowers  the  Minister 
of  Mines  to  fix  the  prices  of  coal  and  to  grant  subsidies  to  min«s 
that  are  inadequately  exploited.  A  national  wheat  board  was  created 
by  a  law,  August  15,  1936,  to  control  production,  fix  prices,  apportion 
sales  to  millers,  provide  credit,  and  grant  export  subsidies  when 
.necessary.  The  board  will  have  a  monopoly  of  the  import  and  ex- 
port trade  in  wheat,  flour,  and  cereals.  The  export  credit  insurance 
law  was  amended  August  25.  Other  laws  passed  in  1936  provided 
aid  and  credit  for  small-siz  d  commercial  and  industrial  enterprises, 
gave  temporary  assistance  to  agricultural  projects,  and  authorized 
delay  in  payments  by  merchants,  industrialists,  and  artisans.  The 
40-hour  week  was  established  in  1936,  and  a  law  dated  December  31, 
supplemented  by  a  decree  on  January  16,^  1937,  provided  that  all  col- 
lective labor  disputes  in  commerce  and  mdustry  must,  be  submitted 
to  conciliation  and  arbitration.  A  national  committee  has  been  ap- 
pointed to  assist  in  enforcing  orders  to  restrict  to  specified  regions  the 
prodiictio^i  of  wines  bearing  certain  regional  names,  and  to  prohibit 
the  shipment  of  such  wines  without  an  official  certificate. 

GevTrmny. — An  administrative  order,  July  7,  1936,  directed  coordi- 
nation of  the  regional  economic  chambers  with  the  so-called  groups  of 
business ;  a  reduction  in  fees  required  for  compulsory  membership  of 
business  firms  in  the  groups;  and  the  creation  of  special  courts  of 
honor  connected  with  the  regional  economic  chambers,  and  a  centra) 
court  of  honor  connected  with  the  Reich  economic  chamber. 

Under  the  second  4-year  plan  proclaimed  in  September  1936,  fur- 
ther efforts  will  be  made  to  make  Germany  independent  of  foreign 
supplies  of  industrial  raw  materials.  A  decree  issued  on  October 
23,  1936,  named  6  business  groups  that  will  participate  in  the  plan, 
representing  production  of  raw  materials,  distribution  of  raw  ma- 
terials, labor,  agricultural  production,  prices,  and  foreign  exchange. 
An  order  issued  by  the  Minister  of  Economics,  November  12,  set  out 
the  Government  plan  for  compulsory  organization  of  industry. 

In  September  1936  warnings  were  issued  with  respect  to  advances 
in  the  price  of  food  or  rentals.  Enticement  of  employees  of  a  com- 
petitor by  offering  higher  wages  was  denounced  as  an  unfair  method 
of  competition.  In  October  a  new  price  commissioner  was  appointed, 
with  authority  to  fix  just  prices  for  goods  and  services  of  all  kinds. 
Several  orders  were  issued  prohibiting  price  increases  in  specific  in- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEOR  267 

dustries,  and  on  November  26  two  decrees  were  issued,  with  an  ex- 
ecutive order  on  November  30,  prohibiting  any  increase  in  the  price 
of  commodities  and  services,  incUiding  rents,  above  the  level  of 
October  18,  1936.  These  orders  did  not  apply  to  foreign  trade  which 
is  under  special  rules  issued  by  the  import  control  boards. 

Under  a  decree  dated  January  26,  1937,  all  private  stocks  of  plat- 
inum, silver,  copper,  lead,  tin,  nickel,  or  zinc,  must  be  delivered  to  a 
governmental  board  for  sale  at  prices  and  under  terms  fixed  by  the 
board.  The  Government  has  effected  a  plan  for  control  of  the  supply 
of  skilled  labor;  work  books  are  now  required  and  a  worker  must 
obtain  a  permit  before  he  may  change  his  occupation.  The  Reich  has 
divested  itself  of  a  number  of  participations  in  private  enterprise 
undertaken  during  the  depression. 

A  law  dated  September  30,  1936,  authorized  monopoly  control  of 
domestic  production  and  importation  of  agricultural  products  to  be 
named  by  further  ordinances. 

A  law 'dated  January  26,  1937,  designed  to  prevent  absentee  owner- 
ship and  speculative  sales,  requires  official  approval  for  sale  or  trans- 
fer of  all  agricultural  property  in  excess  of  2  hectares  (5  acres). 

Two  new  stock  company  laws  were  passed  on  January  30,  1937. 
In  November  1936,  the  foreign  exchange  board  announced  that  steps 
would  be  taken  toward  confiscation  of  foreign  securities,  and  on  No- 
vember 19  a  decree  was  issued  under  which  securities  to  be  named 
from  time  to  time  by  the  board  should  be  delivered  for  confiscation, 
to  the  foreign  exchange  bank.  The  law  against  economic  sabotage, 
passed  in  December  1936,  provided  capital  punishment  for  persons 
who,  in  violation  of  exchange  regulations,  leave  their  property  abroad 
or  transfer  it  to  parties  abroad. 

Great  Britain. — A  proposed  enabling  act  to  provide  self-government 
in  industry  was  introduced  in  the  British  Parliament  during  the  past 
session  but  failed  to  pass.  Regulation  has  been  effected  through  the 
Coal  Mines  Act  and  the  Cotton  Spinning  Industries  Act,  and  some 
voluntary  schemes  toward  dismantling  of  inefficient  plants  have  been 
attempted  through  the  reconstruction  levy  in  the  flour  milling  and 
shipbuilding  industries. 

Report  of  the  Food  Council  to  the  Board  of  Trade,  dated  June  26, 
1936,  reviewed  the  schemes  in  operation  for  fixing  maximum  prices  of 
bread,  and  a  further  report  on  December  3,  1936,  covered  the  pigs 
and  bacon  marketing  schemes.  Report  of  the  Milk  Reorganization 
Commission  of  the  progress  of  the  milk  marketing  boards,  was  pre- 
sented in  December  1936;  and  recommendations  were  made  for  crea- 
tion of  a  permanent  milk  commission  with  authority  to  fix  prices, 
disburse  government  subsidies,  and  direct  the  operation  of  milk  mar- 
keting boards.  A  Marketing  of  Eggs  Act  was  passed  in  Northern 
Ireland  in  1936. 

The  Petroleum  Transfer  of  Licenses  Act  of  July  14,  1936,  amends 
the  Petroleum  Consolidation  Act  of  1928.  The  Key  Industries  Duties 
Act  was  extended  for  ten  years  from  August  19,  1936. 

Greece. — A  committee  was  appointed  in  1936  to  present  a  plan  for 
organization  of  production  and  economic  development.  The  finance 
minister  suggested  a  corporative  system  under  which  each  branch  of 
production  should  be  united  in  a  federation  under  State  supervision, 
to  determine  all  questions  concerning  trade,  industry,  and  agriculture. 


268  CONCENTRATIQN  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEJR 

Hungary. — A  decree  issued  on  December  19,  1936,  provided  that  a 
price-control  committee  shall  supervise  regularly  the  prices  of  staple 
goods,  domestic  and  imported.  The  president  of  the  committee  may 
require  reports  as  to  the  prices  at  which  goods  are  sold ;  if  these  are 
deemed  unjustifiably  high,  certain  penalties  may  be  imposed,  favor 
granted  regarding  taxation  and  duties  may  be  withdrawn,  the  firm 
may  be  excluded  from  public  bids,  its  license  may  be  revoked,  or  other 
means  taken  against  the  enterprise. 

India. — Amendments  to  the  Indian  Companies  Act,  effective  on 
January  15,  1937,  further  safeguard  the  interests  of  shareholders. 

International. — A  sugar  agreement  was  entered  into  in  London  in 
May  1937,  to  be  administered  by  an  international  sugar  council.  Basic 
export  quotas  were  fixed  for  cane  and  beet  sugar  producers  represent- 
ing almost  90  percent  of  the  world's  output;  and  the  contracting 
parties  agreed  not  to  increase  their  production  during  the  5  years 
beginning  September  1,  1937. 

An  international  coffee  conference  held  at  Bogota,  Colombia,  in 
October  1936,  resulted  in  establishment  of  a  Pan  American  coffee 
bureau  in  New  York.  Surplus  stocks  will  be  impounded.  Further 
conferences  were  scheduled  for  1937.  In  November  1936  the  interna- 
tional tea  committee  fixed  the  export  quota  for  the  year  beginning 
April  1,  1937,  at  821/2  percent. 

A  revised  tin-restriction  agreement  was  ratified  on  January  5,  1937, 
effective  for  5  years.  Producers  of  iron  and  steel,  in  Great  Britain, 
Germany,  Austria,  Czechoslovakia,  Hungary,  Italy,  Poland,  Rumania, 
Sweden,  and  Yugoslavia  are  parties  to  an  international  scrap-iron 
convention  signed  in  the  spring  of  1937,  under  which  a  central  office 
at  London  will  purchase  for  all  of  the  members  according  to  quotas 
allotted  and  under  uniform  terms.  Producers  of  cement  in  Great 
Britain,  Belgium,  Germany,  France,  Netherlands,  Yugoslavia,  and 
Scandinavian  countries  entered  into  an  agreement  in  1937  which 
deals  with  production  quotas  and  determination  of  prices. 

An  international  cartel  regulating  prices  and  terms  of  sale  for 
sodium  chlorate,  was  entered  into  on  March  2,  1937,  by  producers  in 
Czechoslovakia,  France,  Italy,  Switzerland,  Germany,  and  Sweden, 
The  international  nitrate  cartel  expired  on  June  30,  1936,  due  to 
withdrawal  of  the  Chilean  producers,  and  a  European  cartel  com- 
prising producers  of  synthetic  nitrogen  was  established. 

The  reciprocal  tariff  agreement  entered  into  by  the  United  States 
with  Nicaragua  on  March  11,  1936,  became  effective  October  1,  1936; 
that  with  Finland  dated  May  18,  1936,  was  made  effective  November 
2,  1936.  Further  agreements  were  negotiated  with  Costa  Rica  on 
November  28,  1936,  effective  August  2,  1937;  and  with  El  Salvador 
on  February  19,  1937,  effective  March  31,  1937. 

Italy. — Since  devaluation,  the  policy  of  the  Government  has  been 
to  prevent  price  increase  and  generally  to  peg  prices  at  the  level  of 
September  1936;  but  in  order  to  permit  necessary  adjustments,  a 
Royal  ordinance  dated  October  7,  1936,  provided  for  fixing  of  a  maxi- 
mum price  by  &.  central  committee  comprising  Government  officials 
and  representatives  of  employers'  and  employees'  federations. 

JapQU. — Under  an  Imperial  ordinance  of  July  3,  1936,  the  law 
for  control  of  important  industries  was  extended  for  a  second  5 
years  from  August  11,  1936.  Plans  of  the  Central  Raw  Silk  Associa- 
tion  include  control   of  production,  price   fixing,   consolidation   of 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEK  269 

plants,  restriction  of  speculation,  financial  aid,  and  international 
agreements  for  distribution  and  sale. 

Latvia. — The  law  of  industry  and  craft,  of  July  11,  1936,  supple- 
mented by  an  act  of  January  7,  1937,  required  all  industrial  enter- 
prises (except  electric-power  undertakings)  which  are  not  owned  and 
controlled  by  the  state,  to  obtain  a  license  from  the  Ministry  of 
Finance,  or  in  the  case  of  dairies  and  abattoirs,  from  the  Ministry 
of  Agriculture.  Conditions  under  which  licenses  will  be  issued  may 
establish  complete  control  of  industrial  production.  A  law  dated 
January  20,  1937,  established  a  central  organization  which  will  have 
monopoly  rights  in  the  purchase  and  sale  of  wool,  rawhides  and  skins, 
and  undres&.^d  furs.  A  law  of  January  23,  1937,  provided  for  a 
central  union  to  combine  all  consumers'  cooperatives,  and  to  assist  the 
Government  in  agricultural  .plans. 

Lithuania. — A  law  dated  August  14,  1936,  subjected  exports  to 
license  requirements.  A  law  passed  on  April  23,  1937,  effective  Sep- 
tember 1,  required  the  registration  of  all  commercial  and  industrial 
enterprises  for  the  purpose  of  regulating  commerce  and  industry, 
preventing  willful  bankruptcies,  unfair  competition,  and  violation  of 
tax  measures. 

Mexico. — A  law  passed  August  1936  required  that  merchants  and 
industrialists  shall  be  registered  and  organized  into  a  confederation 
of  chambers  of  commerce  and  industry.  The  expropriation  law  dated 
November  25,  1936,  lists  a  number  of  enterprises  that  shall  be  deemed 
public  utilities  and  therefore  subject  to  expropriation  proceedings. 

Netherlands. — Following  currency  depreciation  in  1936,  an  emer- 
gency price-control  law  was  passed,  authorizing  the  Minister  of  Com- 
merce to  prescribe  maximum  prices  for  the  wholesale  and  retail  trade 
and  for  some  services.  Prices  and  rents  may  not  be  increased,  and 
large  stores  of  goods  may  not  be  accumulated,  without  governmental 
sanction.  A  constitutional  amendment  bill  proposed  in  1936  would 
authorize  creation  of  public  bodies  for  the  regulation  of  industry^ 
trade,  and  the  professions.  Laws  have  also  been  proposed  to  change 
emergency  or  crisis  measures  into  permanent  laws. 

New  Zealand. — The  Industrial  Efficiency  Act  of  October  29,  1936, 
gave  to  the  Government  wide  powers  of  control  over  industry  and 
trade.  Part  1  provided  for  a  bureau  of  industry  to  investigate  and 
report  as  to  organization  of  industries,  their  capitalization,  the  ren- 
dering of  assistance  by  way  of  subsidies,  loans,  grants,  tariff  conces- 
sions, embargoes,  and  other  means;  the  adoption  of  uniform  methods 
of  accounting  and  costing;  standardization  of  products,  processes,  or 
materials;  the  training  of  workers;  marketing  and  distribution  of 
products  and  the  purchase  of  raw  materials ;  and  anymatters  relating 
to  employment.  Part  2  of  the  law  provided  for  industrial  plans  to  be 
prescribed  by  the  Minister  of  Industries  and  Commerce,  upon  advice 
of  the  Bureau  of  Industry.  Part  3  covered  registration  and  licensing 
of  such  industries  as  may  be  named  by  the  minister.  Part  4  required 
consideration  and  report  by  the  bureau  on  applications  for  loans 
under  the  State  Advances  Corporation  Act  of  1936  and  on  grants 
and  loans  under  the  Employment  Promotion  Act  of  1936.  Upon 
recommendation  of  the  bureau,  orders-in-council  may  be  issued  by  the 
Governor  General  covering  the  registration  of  persons  and  firms  and 
the  licensing  of  industries;  reports  to  be  required  of  industrial  firms; 
fixation  of  prices  or  rates  for  any  class  of  goods  or  services ;  rates  of 


270  CONCENTKATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

royalties,  fees,  discounts,  rebates,  concessions,  or  considerations  of  any 
kind  in  respect  of  goods  or  services  or  in  respect  of  any  patent  or 
proprietary  rights;  the  control  of  production  by  fixing  of  quotas  or 
otherwise;  and  the  standardization  and  simplification  of  materials, 
processes,  and  products. 

A  number  of  semiprivate  organizations  have  been  completely  na- 
tionalized, including  the  railways,  the  reserve  bank,  and  the  mortgage 
corporation.  The  industrial  conciliation  and  arbitration  law  was 
amended  on  June  8,  1936,  to  include  compulsory  features. 

Under  the  Primary  Products  Marketing  Act  of  1936,  the  Govern- 
ment has  assumed  control  of  agricultural  and  dairy  products.  The 
Minister  of  Marketing  buys  the  produce  from  the  farmer  at  a  guar- 
anteed price  for  the  whole  season  and  markets  it  with  the  aid  of  pro- 
fessional distributors  at  a  fixed  price.  If  export  sales  are  not  made  at 
figures  high  enough  to  cover  the  guaranteed  price  to  producers,  the 
deficit  is  met  by  the  Government. 

Paraguay. — A  new  Department  of  Industries  and  Monopolies  under 
the  Minister  of  Agriculture,  to  study  questions  of  industrial  develop- 
ment, tariff  protection,  and  the  possibility  of  Government  monopolies, 
was  created  by  presidential  decree  on  September  15,  1936.  A  decree 
law  passed  as  a  health  measure  on  June  15,  1936,  provided  for  regida- 
tion  of  production,  transportation,  and  sale  of  food,  pharmaceutical 
and  beauty  products. 

Psm. — A  presidential  decree  dated  July  16,  1936,  established  gov- 
ernmental control  of  medicinal  products,  drugs,  and  pharmaceutical 
specialties  which  are  declared  to  be  of  prime  necessity  and  therefore 
subject  to  the  same  regulatory  measures  as  staple  foodstuffs. 

Poland, — A  Government  commissioner  has  been  appointed  to  control 
prices  of  certain  necessary  commodities,  including  food,  clothing,  oil, 
coal,  iron,  and  bricks.  A  presidential  decree  effective  on  September  22, 
1936,  lists  certain  properties  which  are  destined  for  compulsory  sale  to 
the  State  Agrarian  Bank. 

Portugal. — A' decree  dated  May  15,  1937,  provided  for  appointment 
of  a  committee  which  shall  organize  the  cotton  industry,  regulate  im- 
ports of  raw  cotton,  establish  conditions  under  which  importers  shall 
engage  in  business,  and  encourage  production  of  cotton  in  the  Portu- 
guese colonies. 

Rumania. — A  law  dated  April  29,  1936,  provided  for  a  Supreme 
Economic  Council  representing  agriculture,  commerce,  industry,  labor, 
and  Government  officials,  for  study  and  investigation  of  problems  re- 
garding foreign  commerce,  the  valorization  of  agricultural  products, 
the  regulation  of  labor,  and  other  economic,  financial,  and  social  prob- 
lems. The  council  will  also  make  recommendations  for  the  negotia- 
tion of  trade  conventions. 

Spain. — A  decree  dated  December  2, 1936,  prescribed  regulations  for 
the  exportation  of  national  products  of  Spain.  Export  permits  will 
be  required,  and  if  the  value  declared  by  the  exporter  is  considered 
too  low  the  Ministry  of  Finance  may  take  possession  of  the  goods,  pay- 
ing for  them  the  price  at  which  they  were  declared. 

Three  decrees  in  Catalonia  dated  October  27,  1936,  provide  for 
socialization  of  large  industries  and  land  holdings,  organization  of 
municipalities  into  social  economic  units,  and  division  of  the  state 
into  nine  economic  areas.    A  plan  has  been  oflfered  for  a  central  bank 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR  271 

to  impound  the  gains  of  profitable  enterprise  and  extend  credit  or 
compensate  other  industries  for  their  losses. 

Switzerlcmd. — A  decree  effective  on  July  1, 1936,  gives  to  the  Federal 
Price  Control  Office  the  power  to  check  price  movements  deemed  harm- 
ful to  producers  or  consiuners.  A  pure  food  ordinance  dated  May  28, 
1936,  provided  for  regulation  of  the  sale  of  foodstuffs,  laying  down 
standards  of  purity,  and  applying  also  to  certain  chemicals  in  the 
manufacture  of  clothing,  cosmetics,  and  toilet  preparations. 

Turkey. — Under  a  law  dated  June  9,  1936,  all  exporters  are  placed 
under  license. 

Venezuela. — A  new  constitution  adopted  July  21,  1936,  restates  the 
power  of  the  Government  to  legislate  for  the  entire  country  on  many 
matters  listed  therein.  The  Govermnent  reserves  control  of  salt  de- 
posits, unoccupied  lands  and  products  thereof,  pearl-oyster  beds,  and 
mines. 


EXHIBIT  9 

[Federal  Trade  Commisison] 

FOREIGN  TRADE  WORK 

Excerpts  from  Annual  Report  of  the  Federal  Trade  CoMMissiON 
FOR  THE  Fiscal  Year  Ending  June  30, 1938 

November  30,  1938. 
Fedebal  Trade  Commission 

Garland  S.  Ferguson,  Chairman;  Charles  H.  March  ;  Ewin  L.  Davis  ;  W.  A. 
Aybes  ;  Robert  E.  Freer;  Otis  B.  Johnson,  Secretary 

Foreign-trade  work  of  the  Commission  includes  administration  of 
the  Export  Trade  Act  and  inquiries  under  section  6  (h)  of  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission  Act.  This  work  is  done  by  the  Export  Trade 
Section,  under  direction  of  the  Chief  Counsel. 

THE  EXPORT  TRADE  ACT    ( WEBB-POMERENE  LAW) 

The  Export  Trade  Act,  known  also  as  the  Webb-Pomerene  law, 
which  was  passed  in  1918,  provides  that  nothing  contained  in  the 
Sherman  Act  (passed  in  1890)  shall  be  construed  as  declaring  to  be 
illegal  any  combinations  or  "associations"  entered  into  for  the  sole  pur- 
pose of  engaging  in,  and  actually  solely  engaged  in,  export  trade  or 
agreements  or  acts  done  in  aforesaid  export  trade  by  such  associations, 
under  certain  safeguarding  provisions  set  out  in  the  law. 

The  Export  Trade  Act  also  provides  that  nothing  contained  in  sec- 
tion 7  of  the  Clayton  Act  (passed  in  1914)  "shall  be  construed  to  forbid 
the  acquisition  or  ownership  by  any  corporation  of  the  whole  or  any 
part  of  the  stock  or  other  capital  of  any  corporation  organized  solely 
for  the  purpose  of  engaging  in  export  trade,  and  actually  eltigaged 
solely  in  such  export  trade,  unless  the  effect  of  such  acquisit^ion  or 
ownership  may  be  to  restrain  trade  or  substantially  lessen  competition 
within  the  United  States." 

An  export  trade  association  must  be  entered  into  for  the  sole  pur- 
pose of  engaging  in  export  trade  from  the  United  States  to  foreign 
countries.  It  may  not  produce,  manufacture,  or  sell  for  consumption 
or  resale  in  the  domestic  market ;  nor  may  it  enter  into  any  agreement 
or  act  in  restraint  of  trade  within  the  United  States  or  in  restraint  of 
the  export  trade  of  a  domestic  competitior.  Such  association  must  not 
either  in  the  United  States  or  elsewhere  enter  into  any  agreement  or 
conspiracy  or  do  any  act  which  artificially  or  intentionally  enhances  or 
depresses  prices  within  the  United  States  of  commodities  of  the  class 
exported  by  such  association  or  which  substantially  lessens  competi- 
272     ' 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  273 

tion  within  the  United  States.  The  prohibition  against  unfair 
methods  of  competition  contained  in  the  Federal  Trade  Commission 
Act  is  extended  to  competitors  engaged  in  export  trade  even  though 
the  acts  constituting  such  unfair  metliods  are  done  without  the  terri- 
torial jurisdiction  of  the  United  States. 

The  organization  papers  of  such  export  trade  groups  are  placed  on 
file  with  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  supplemented  by  annual  re- 
ports and  such  other  information  as  the  Commission  may  require  as 
to  their  business,  conduct,  practices,  management,  and  relation  to  other 
associations,  corporations,  partnerships,  and  individuals.  The  law 
provides  for  a  procedure  to  be  followed  in  case  of  violation  of  its  terms. 

EXPORTS  SHOW  SUBSTANTIAL  INCREASE 

Shipments  by  export-trade  associations  during  1937  amounted  to 
$197,875,832,  which  was  a  substantial  increase  (^8,579,307)  over  ex- 
ports of  1936.  The  products  shipped,  and  money  value  thereof,  are 
as  follows: 


Commodities 


1936 


Metals  and  metal  products,  copper,  iron  and  steel,  metal  lath,  machinery, 
railway  equipment,  pipes  and  valves,  screws,  electrical  apparatus,  and 
signal  apparatus 

Products  of  mines  and  wells,  crude  sulfur,  phosphate  rock,  carbon  black 

Lumber  and  wood  products,  pine,  fir,  hardwood,  redwood,  walnut,  plywood, 
tool  handles,  barrel  and  box  shocks,  and  wood  naval  stores 

Foodstuffs,  such  as  milk,  meat,  sugar,  flour,  fruit  (fresh,  canned,  and  dried), 
and  rice 

Other  manufactured  goods,  rubber,  paper,  textiles>  glass,  cement,  abrasives, 
and  chemicals - 

Total. 


$40,  507, 335 
40, 780,  283 

8,  533, 374 

21,  250,  433 

38,  225, 100 


149, 296,  525 


958. 850 
580,219 

456, 922 

921,  343 

958,  498 


197, 875, 832 


Early  in  1937  exports  were  materially  increased,  partly  on  orders 
placed  in  1936.  This  increase  continued  in  some  markets,  but  ship- 
ments to  the  Orient  lessened  as  the  Sino-Japanese  war  advanced,  and 
associations  dependent  upon  the  Chinese  trade  were  materially  affected 
by  the  chaotic  conditions  in  that  market.  Increased  freight  rates  late 
in  1937  were  preceded  by  a  spurt  of  buying  to  replenish  stocks  before 
the  new  rates  were  made  effective,  but  later  increased  transportation 
costs  were  an  important  factor  in  lessening  sales.  As  costs  began  to 
reflect  such  factors  as  the  higher  prices  of  raw  materials,  labor  costs, 
loss  through  strikes,  and  other  domestic  conditions,  export  prices  were 
increased,  and  it  was  more  difficult  to  meet  the  competition  of  foreign 
producers  whose  costs  were  not  increasing  in  proportion. 

The  growii;g  effort  on  tlie  part  of  foreign  countries  to  increase  pro- 
duction to  the  point  of  supplying  domestic  needs,  and  the  continuance 
of  foreign-exchange  controls  in  some  countries,  have  lessened  ship- 
ments- of  some  American  products,  notably  foodstuffs.  Associations 
shipping  to  the  German  market  found  it  difficult  to  obtain  excl  ange. 
In  Argentina,  preferences  given  to  goods  from  Germany  and  Britain, 
under  special  treaties,  resulted  in  a  scarcity  of  exchange  for  American 
goods.    This  was  true  to  some  extent  in  other  Latin  American  countries. 

In  some  markets,  agreements  negotiated  under  tlie  ITnited  States 
Trade  Agreements  Act  liave  removed  or  lessened  restrictions  and  paved 


274  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEK 

Ihe  way  for  better  business  relations.  Members  of  the  Webb-Pomerene 
law  groups  were  in  a  position  to  place  their  problems  before  the  nego- 
tiators through  the  association  officers. 

Collective  bargaining  in  the  matter  of  forwarding  and  freight  rates 
proved  also  of  advantage  to  the  associations.  Groups  that  operate  as 
selling  agencies  reduce  the  cost  of  marketing  for  all  of  the  member 
companies.  Uniform  terms  of  sale  and  contract  forms,  standardiza- 
tion of  products  and  packing  methods,  pooling  of  shipments,  and  the 
elimination  of  impracticable  and  unsound  trade  customs,  by  association 
action,  make  for  efficiency  and  economy  in  the  export  business.  Ship- 
ments may  be  so  controlled  as  to  prevent  periodic  glutting  of  foreign 
markets.  It  is  also  possible  to  split  large  orders  between  the  mem- 
bers of  an  association  and  thereby  effect  prompt  shipment  to  the  satis- 
faction of  the  foreign  purchaser.  In  some  countries,  such  as  the  Soviet 
Union,  where  buying  is  centralized,  the  association  provides  a  single 
contact  for  all  of  the  members'  products. 

New  markets  have  been  developed  through  joint  effort  and  expense; 
credit  losses  and  claims  for  unsatisfactory  shipments  have  been  re- 
duced ;  and  the  newer  associations  report  substantial  increase  in  export 
business  over  that  obtained  through  individual  sales  prior  to  their 
organization. 

FORTY-FOUR  EXPORT  ASSOCIATIONS  IN  OPERATION 

Forty-four  associations  were  on  file  with  the  Federal  Trade  Commis- 
sion at  the  close  of  the  fiscal  year,  June  30,  1938.  These  included  a 
new  group  formed  in  October  1937,  the  Rice  Export  Association,  com- 
prising 23  mills  located  in  Louisiana,  Texas,  and  Arkansas,  with  a 
headquarters  office  in  New  Orleans.  Two  associations  were  dissolved 
during  the  year,  the  Inter- America  Exporters,  Inc.,  which  had  been 
organized  to  ship  fresh  fruit,  and  the  Scrap  Export  Associates  of 
America,  which  liad  been  formed  in  June  1937  to  ship  scrap  iron  and 
steel  but  did  not  become  operative,  finally  dissolving  in  November  of 
that  year.     The  present  list  is  as  follows : 

American   Box   Shook  Export  Associa-  California    Pruna    Export    Association, 

tion,     Barr     Building,     Washington,  1  Drumm  Street,  San  Francisco. 

D.  C.  Carbon   Black   Export,   Inc.,   500  Fifth 

American    Hardwood    Exporters,    Inc.,  Avenue,  New  York. 

G04    Carondelet    Building,    New    Or-  Cement  Export  Co.,  Inc.,  150  Broadway, 

leans.  New  York. 

American    Locomotive    Sales    Corpora-  Copper  Exporters,   Inc.,  50  Broadway, 

tioii,  30  Church  Street,  New  York.  New  York. 

American  Paper  Exports,  Inc.,  75  West  Douglas  Fir  Export  Co.,  Henry  Build- 
Street,  New  York.  ing,   Seattle,  Wash. 

American    Provisions    Export    Co.,    SO  Durex  Abrasives  Corporation,  63  Wall 

East  Jackson  Boulevard,  Chicago.  Street,  New  York. 

American    Soda    Pulp   Export   Associa-  Electrical    Apparatus    Export    Associa- 
tion, 230  Park  Avenue,  New  York.  tion.  70  Pine  Street,  New  York. 

American    Spring    Manufacturers    Ex-  Export  Screw  Association  of  the  United 

port   Association,   30  Church    Street,  States,  23  Acorn  Street,  Providence, 

New  York.  R.  I. 

American    Tire    Mmufacturers   Export  Florida   Hard  Rock  Phosphate  Export 

Association,   30  Church   Street,   New  Association,     Savannah     Bank     and 

York.  Trust  Building,   Savannah,  Ga. 

California    Alkali    Export    Association,  General  Milk  Co.,  Inc.,  19  Rector  Street, 

523  West  Sixth  Street,  Los  Angeles.  New  York. 

Califoi-nia    Dried    Fruit    Export    Asso-  Goodyear   Tire  &  Rubber  Export  Co., 

ciation,  1  Drumm  Street,  San  Fran-  1144     East     Market     Street,     Akron, 

Cisco.  Ohio. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  275 

Grapefruit    Distributors,    Inc.,    Daven-  Shook  Exporters  Association,  Stahlman 

port,  Fla.  Building,  Nashville,  Tenn. 

Metal     Lath     Export     Association,    47  Signal  Export  Association,  420  Lexing- 

West  Thirty-fourth  Street,  New  York.        ton   Avenue,  New  York. 

Northwest    Dried    Fruit    Export    Asso-  Steel   Export   Association    of   America, 

ciation.    Title    and    Trust    Building,        75  West  Street,  New  York. 

Portland,  Oreg.  Sugar  Export  Corporation,  120  Wall 
Pacific  Flour  Export  Co.,  care  of  Fisher        Street,  New  York. 

Flouring  Mills  Co.,  Seattle,  Wash.  Sulphur  Export  Corporation,  420  Lex- 
Pacific      Forest      Industries,      Taconia        ington    Avenue,    New    York. 

Building,  Tacoma,  Wash.  Textile  Export  Association  of  the 
Pacific  Fresh  Fruit  Export  Association,        United    States,   320   Broadway,   New 

3:-!3  Pine  Street,  San  Francisco.  Ynrk. 

Phosphate  Export  Association,  3^3  Sev-  United    States   Alkali    Export   Associa- 

enth  Avenue,  New  York  tion.  Inc.,  11  Broadway,  New  York. 

Pipe  Fittings  and  Valve  Export  Asso-  United     States     Handle     Export     Co., 

ciation,  1421  Chestnut  Street,  Phila-        Piqua,  Ohio. 

delphia.  Walnut  Export  Sales  Co.,  Inc.,  Twelfth 
Plate  Glass  Export  Corporation,  Grant        Street  and  Kaw  River,  Kansas  City, 

Building,   Pittsburgh.  Kans. 

Redwood  Export  Co.,  405  Montgomery  Walworth    International    Co.,    00    East 

Street,   San  Francisco.  ■  Forty-second    Street,    New    York. 

Rice    Export    Association,    1103    Queen  Wood  Naval  Stores  Export  Association, 

and  Crescent  Building,  New  Orleans.  1220  Delaware  Trust  Building,  Wil- 
Rubber    Exiwrt   Association,   19   Good-        mington.  Del. 

year  Avenue,  Akron,  Ohio. 

SUPPLEMENTAL  REPORT   ON    ANTIDUMPING   LEGISLATION 

In  Jtme  1938,  tire  Commission  presented  to  Congress  a  Supplemelital 
Report  on  Antidiniiping  Legislation  and  Other  Import  Regulations 
in  the  United  States  and  Foreign  Countries,  which  brought  to  date 
material  in  a  report  on  the  same,  subject  published  in  1934  as  Senate 
Document  No.  Ili2,  Seventy-third  Congre.ss,  second  session. 

This  work  was  done  under  the  provisions  of  section  6  (h)  of  the 
Federal  Trade  Commission  Act  which  directs  the  Commission  to  "in- 
vestigate, from  time  to  time,  trade  conditions  in  and  with  foreign 
countries  where  associations,  combinations,  or  practices  of  manufac- 
turers, merchants,  or  traders,  or  other  conditions,  may  affect  the  for- 
eign trade  of  the  United  States." 

TKUST  LAWS  AND  UNFAIR  COMPETITION  IN  FOREIGN  COUNTRIES 

Also  under  section  6  (h)  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act,  the 
Connnission  follows  trust  legislation  and  unfair  competition  in  for- 
eign countries.     Recent  measures  are  briefly  summarized. 

Argentina. — A  governmental  connnittee  appointed  to  study  the 
petroleum  situation  re])orted  in  1937,  reconnnending  establishment  of 
a  National  Petroleum  Council  to  control  and  administer  reserves,  or- 
ganize petroleum  companies  with  Government  and  private  capital, 
establish,  ])ipe  lines,  and  regulate  the  im])ort  and  export  trade. 

Three  decrees  were  issued  by  the  President  in  1938  for  regulation 
of  flour  milling,  fixing  official  standards  for  the  different  grades, 
authorizing  the  Ministrv  of  Agriculture  to  regulate  and  control  the 
activities  of  the  Chamber  of  Millers,  and  establishing  an  advisory 
board  comprising  millers,  pastry  makers,  and  bakers,  to  settle  contro- 
versies in  the  industrv  and  to  present  reconuiiendations  for  legislation. 

A  decree  published  on  January  30,  1938,  established  an  Office  of 
Commercial  Policy  in  the  Ministry  of  Agriculture  to  conduct  general 

257700 — 41— Xo.  t> 10 


276  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR 

studies  of  domestic  and  foreign  economic  conditions  in  connection 
with  production,  trade,  and  consumption,  internal  tax  systems,  eco- 
nomic balances,  internal  commercial  policy,  customs  tarins,  commer- 
cial treaties,  import  quotas,  embargoes,  temporary  importation,  im- 
port premiums,  dumping,  drawbacks,  clearing  and  compensation 
agreements,  arid  exchange  control. 

Belgivmi. — ^A  decree  dated  January  13,  1937,  prohibited  the  exten- 
sion of  certain  retail  sales  establishments  (chain  and  department 
stores)  and  the  period  of"  enforcement  was  extended  to  the  end  of 
1938  by  further  decrees.  As  authorized  by  law  and  royal  order  on 
January  15,  1938,  and  by  ministerial  orders  on  April  30,  1938,  a 
National  Office  of  Milk  and  Its  Derivatives  has  been  established  to 
control  the  production  and  sale  of  milk,  butter,  and  cheese,  and  to 
promote  and  improve  the  distribution  and  marketing  of  milk  and  its 
derivatives. 

Bolivia. — A  decree  of  April  28,  1938,  provided  further  Government 
supervision  of  the  development  and  management  of  stock  companies 
in  order  to  prevent  fraudulent  acts. 

Brazil. — A  new  constitution  decreed  by  the  President  and  published 
on  November  11,  1937,  provided  for  complete  reorganization  of  the 
Government  by  the  President  as  supreme  authority  of  the  state,  in- 
cluding the  power  to  dissolve  and  reconstitute  legislative  bodies  and 
the  federal  courts. 

Decree  No.  366,  published  on  April  12,  1938,  added  to  the  mining 
code  regulations  governing  the  subsoil  deposits  of  petroleum  and  nat- 
ural gas.  These  and  mineral  deposits  are  the  property  of  the  National 
Government.  Decree  No.  395  of  April  29,  1938,  completed  nationali- 
zation of  the  petroleum  industry.  Production,  refining,  importation, 
exportation,  and  distribution  of  petroleum  and  its  products  are  subject 
to  regulations  to  be  issued  by  a  newly  created  National  Petroleum 
Council.  Concessions  shall  be  granted  only  to  Brazilians  and  Bra- 
zilian enterprises. 

Camada. — Following  decision  of  the  Privy  Council  at  London  in 
1937,  holding  the  Natural  Products  Marketing  Act  to  be  unconstitu- 
tional, a  Canadian  order  in  council  dated  December  22,  1937,  canceled 
all  the  marketing  schemes  set  up  under  the  act.  But  in  some  cases 
growers  have  organized  associations  to  carry  on  marketing  schemes 
on  a  voluntary  basis,  including  tobacco  and  cheese  associations  in 
Ontario,  and  m.ilk  and  fruit  associations  in  British  Columbia.  The 
Royal  Commission  on  the  Textile  Industry  completed  its  hearings  and 
presented  a  comprehensive  report  to  the  Minister  of  Finance  in  Jan- 
uary 1938.  In  December  1937  the  Provincial  Legislature  of  British 
Columbia  passed  the  Commodities  Retail  Sales  Act,  which  makes  it 
a  statutory  offense  to  sell  for  less  than  the  price  fixed  by  the  wholesaler 
or  producer. 

Cuha. — The  Petroleum  Act  promulgated  on  May  10,  1938,  effected 
nationalization  of  the  industrj^,  including  petroleum,  naphtha,  natural 
kerosene,  hydrocarbon  gas,  helium,  asphalt,  resin,  and  coal.  All  de- 
posits are  deemed  the  property  of  the  state.  Concessions  are  to  be 
granted  for  deveiopment  of  the  resources. 

Czechoslovakia. — Decree  No.  121.  June  18,  1937,  provided  for  basic 
minimum  prices  in  certain  trades.  Decree  No.  122,  also  dated  June  18, 
amended  the  law  of  December  22.  1933,  Vv-hich  restricted  tlie  establish- 
ment of  single-price  stores  and  extended  the  restriction  to  December 

A 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR  277 

31,  1938.  Decree  No.  148,  June  24,  1937,  extended  until  December  31, 
1938,  provisions  of  a  decree  issued  in  1935  prohibiting  establishment 
of  new  brand  sales  in  certain  industries.  A  decree  dated  June  26, 1937, 
gave  to  the  Ministry  of  Social  Welfare  power  to  declare  binding  cer- 
tain labor  contracts.  A  law  dated  December  21,  1937,  affirmed  and 
prolonged  until  March  31,  1939,  the  effect  of  a  Government  decree 
issued  in  1934,  prohibiting  the  unjustified  closure  of  factories  and 
mass  release  of  employees.  Law  No.  245,  dated  December  21,  1937, 
imposed  a  tax  on  domestic  cartels,  from  which  export  and  inter- 
national cartels  are  exempt. 

Denmark. — New  legislation  in  Denmark  in  1937  extended  the  Gov- 
ernment's control  over  domestic  trade  and  industry  by  providing 
control  of  private  price  agreements  and  forced  arbitration  of ^iabor 
disputes.  A  new  grain  law,  effective  on  January  1,  1938,  sufrersedes 
prior  acts  in  1936  and  1937. 

Ecuador. — Decree  No.  159,  August  9, 1937,  established  absolute  con- 
trol over  the  manufacture,  import,  sale,  and  advertising  of  chemical 
and  biological  products  intended  for  medicinal  or  veterinary  use,  and 
pharamaceutical  specialities.  Registration  is  required,  and  all  adver- 
tising matter  must  be  approved  by  the  Department  of  Health. 

A  presidential  decree  on  October  28,  1937,  created  a  Council  of 
National  Economy  to  centralize  national  statistics,  advise  with  Gov- 
ernment departments  on  economic  and  financing  operations,  customs 
duties  and  fiscal  policies,  and  to  draft  legislation  of  an  economic 
character.  A  decree  dated  December  28,  1937,  established  a  Commis- 
sariat of  Industries,  which  shall  take  immediate  control  over  the 
iiulnstrial  and  manufacturing  production  of  tlie  country  with  respect 
to  commerce.  Representatives  of  the  commissariat  are  empowered 
to  inspect  account  books,  invoices,  and  other  commercial  documents 
regarding  industry  or  manufacture. 

A  decree  published  on  January  7,  1938,  provided  for  the  establish- 
ment of  and  compulsory  membership  in  chambers  of  commerce  which 
shall  have  authority  to  defend  and  develop  national  commerce,  to 
examine  into  the  morality  and  honesty  of  commercial  transactions 
and  into  the  strict  fulfillment  of  contracts  and  obligations  to  which, 
their  members  are  parties,  to  cooperate  with  the  Government  in  the 
study  of  social-economic  problemSj  and  to  require  that  all  merchants 
located  withixi  their  territorial  jurisdiction  join  the  chambers.  They 
also  will  promote  commercial  fairs,  expositions  and  conventions,  un- 
dertake propaganda  in  favor  of  Ecuadoran  products,  and  if  requested 
to  do  so,  may  arbitrate  claims  arising  between  foreign  shippers  and 
Ecuadoran  importers. 

Decrees  No.  45  of  February  16,  1938,  and  No.  9  of  March  9,  1938, 
provided  for  mining  and  petroleum  concessions  under  the  general 
principle  that  private  individuals  or  entities  may  operate  only  as 
concessionaires  for  the  exploitation  of  natural  resources. 

Estonia. — After  several '  years  of  experimenting  with  subsidies, 
equalization  fees,  and  guaranteed  minimum  prices,  in  February  1937, 
Estonia  formed  a  monopoly  for  the  processing  and  exportation  of  all 
livestock  and  meat  products. 

France.— Kcis  dated  June  30,  1937,  and  April  13,  1938,  authorized, 
the  Government  to  take  by  decree  any  measure-  required  to  insure 
repression  of  attacks  on  the  credit  of  the  state,  the  combating  of 
speculation,  economic  recovery,  the  control  of  prices,  the  balancing  of 


278;  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

the  budget,  and  the  defense  of  the  reserve  of  the  Bank  of  France, 
without  control  of  exchange.  Under  this  authority,  a  number  of  de- 
crees have  been  issued.  One  dated  June  30,  1937,  modified  the  mone- 
tary law  of  October  1,  1936.  Another  decree  also  dated  June  30,  1937, 
prescribed  duties  of  the  Departmental  Commission  of  Price  Control 
and  prohibited  any  increase  in  the  wholesale,  semiwholesale^  or  retail 
prices  of  goods  and  foodstuffs  or  in  the  price  lists  applied  in  industrial 
and  commefcial  enterprises  which  were  in  force  on  June  28,  1937. 
The  new  provisions  supersede  those  of  the  Price  Control  Act  of 
August  19,  1936.  Numerous  protests  against  the  prohibition  of  in- 
crease in  price  resulted  in  some  exemptions ;  and  the  decree  was  further 
relaxed  by  a  decree  on  November  7,  1937,  which  authorized  retail  price 
increases  resulting  directly  from  higher  wholesale  prices,  transporta- 
tion charges  and  taxes. 

A  decree  on  April  4,  1938,  provided  for  establishment  of  a  commis- 
sion to  study  ways  and  means  by  which  control  of  production  in  the 
French  industries  may  be  effected,  A  law  dated  July  9,  1937,  effective 
until  January  31,  1938,  conferred  upon  the  Government  special  au- 
thority to  modify  customs  duties  by  decree,  and  amended  the  anti- 
dumping powers  of  the  Government. 

A  company  act  dated  July  24,  1937,  and  decrees  issued  thereunder, 
included  new  provisions  for  the  protection  of  stockholders  and  in- 
vestors. Decrees  dated  August  26  and  October  24,  1937,  modified  the 
Export  Credit  Guarantee  Act  of  August  22.  1936.  Four  decrees  dated 
August  27,  1937,  provided  for  control  of  French  colonial  products, 
including  their  production,  distribution,  exportation  from  the  French 
colonies,  and  importation  into  France  and  into  the  colonial  territories. 

A  decree  on  August  31,  1937,  provided  for  nationalization  of  the 
country's  railroads  under  an  agreement  effective  January  1,  1938, 
whereby  all  main-line  railways  are  taken  over  by  a  new  state-controlled 
company  which  acquires  all  assets,  assumes  all  their  obligations,  and 
will  operate  them  as  a  unit  until  January  1,  1983,  at  which  time  they 
will  revert  to  the  state. 

Gemiany. — A  decree  of  May  24,  1937,  applied  to  mail-order  houses 
the  prohibition  of  establishment  or  expansion  of  retail  shops  covered 
by  the  law  of  May  12,  1933.  A  decree  dated  July  15,  1937,  superseded 
a  decree  of  September  22,  1934,  for  regulation  of  the  domestic  prices 
of  foreign  merchandise,  and  provided  that  the  price  base  shall  be  the 
actual  cost  rather  than  the  market  price  abroad ;  and  profits  and  prices 
charged  by  dealers  in  handling  foreign  merchandise  shall  be  fixfed  by 
the  Reich  Price  Commissioner. 

A  decree  dated  INIarch  13,  1938,  forbade  persons  in  Germany  to  estab- 
lish new  industrial  enterprises,  acquire  existing  concerns,  or  to  form 
branches,  offices,  or  agencies  in  Austria.  This  plan  was  abandoned  and 
the  decree  of  March  13  abrogated  on  April  26,  1938,  after  passage  of 
a  law  published  in  the  Austrian  Gazette  on  April  13,  1938,  which 
authorized  the  Governor  of  Austria  to  control  the  establishment  of 
industrial  enterprises,  and  to  appoint  commissioned  administrators  or 
supervisors  for  all  enterprises  located  therein.  A  decree  published  on 
March  30,  1938,  prohibited  increases  in  prices  and  remunerations  of 
all  kinds,  as  far  as  they  relate  to  goods  of  daily  necessity,  to  the  entire 
agricultural,  handicraft,  and  industrial  production,  and  to  the  ship- 
ment of  goods  of  all  kinds,  within  the  State  of  Austria,  and  in  all  busi- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR  279 

ness  transactions  from  Austria  to  the  other  parts  of  the  Reich.  Excep- 
tions may  be  granted  by  the  Reich  Price  Commissioner.  The  German 
stock  company  law  of  January  30,  1937,  and  subsequent  regulations 
were  made  applicable  to  Austria  by  a  German  decree  dated  April  11, 
1938. 

Great  Britain. — Laws  passed  in  1937  included  the  Livestock  Indus- 
try Act,  July  20, 1937,  which  provides  for  the  regulation  of  importation 
of  livestock  and  meat  (except  bacon),  continuation  of  subsidies  to  pro- 
ducers of  beef  cattle,  the  regulation  of  markets  and  of  central  slaughter 
houses;  the  Control  of  Imports  Amendment  Act,  which  provides  cer- 
tain changes  in  the  act  of  1934;  the  Export  Guarantee  Act,  which 
amends  and  extends  the  authority  of  the  Export  Credit  Guarantee 
Department  of  the  Board  of  Trade;  an  Agricultural  Act;  a  Trade- 
Marks  Amendment  Act  (the  first  major  revision  of  British  trade-mark 
legislation  since  1905) ;  and  the  Factories  Act,  July  30,  1937,  which 
serves  as  a  consolidating  measure  and  repeals  a  number  of  prior  lawb 
regulating  labor  and  factory  conditions. 

A  Special  Committee  on  Share-Pushing,  appointed  by  the  Board  of 
Trade  in  1936,  made  its  report  in  July  1937,  recommending  further 
regulation  of  the  sale  of  stocks  and  shares  in  order  to  safeguard  inves- 
tors. An  important  report  of  the  Import  Duties  Advisory  Committee 
on  the  present  position  and  future  development  of  the  iron  and  steel 
industry  (command  5507)  was  issued  in  July  1937,  with  recommenda- 
tions for  regulation  of  the  industry.  Report  on  an  inquiry  into  the 
costs  and  profits  of  retail  milk  distribution  in  Great  Britain  was  sub- 
mitted by  the  Food  Council  of  the  Board  of  Trade  in  November  1937, 
recommending:  Rationalization  through  concentration  of  processing 
and  distributing  depots,  reduction  in  the  number  of  shops  and  in  the 
expense  of  advertising,  decrease  in  costs  on  book  debts  and  their  collec- 
tion, and  economies  from  simplified  services;  these  ends  to  be  accom- 
plished through  voliuitary  action  by  the  industry,  compulsory  legisla- 
tion, or  a  combination  of  the  two.  Report  of  a  Joint  Committee  on 
Cotton  Trade  Control,  in  October  1937,  proposed  a  bill  which  would 
establish  a  Cotton  Industry  Board  for  further  regulation  of  the  trade, 
covering  all  phases  of  production  and  merchandising  of  cotton  and 
allied  textiles,  including  reduction  of  surplus  capacity,  prevention  of 
waste  through  excessive  competition,  the  regulation  of  production, 
supply,  and  sale,  establishment  of  minimum  prices  or  margins,  insti- 
tution of  pools  and  quotas,  the  imposition  of  levies,  and  legalization  of 
wage  agreements.  The  first  annual  report  of  the  Spindles  Board  was 
issued  in  1938  covering  purchase  of  redundant  mills  and  machinery 
under  the  Cotton  Spinning  Act  of  1936. 

A  coal  bill  introduced  in  1937  would  vest  ownership  and  control  of 
all  unmined  coal  and  mines  in  a  National  Coal  Commission.  Other 
features  include  amendments  to  the  Coal  Mines  Act  of  1930  to  bring 
about  further  amalgamations  in  tlie  mines  and  a  continuance  of  organ- 
ized marketing  schemes.  A  films  bill  would  extend  and  amend  the 
existing  film-cjuota  system  and  set  up  an  advisory  films  council.^  The 
essential  commodities  purchase  bill  would  authorize  further  buying  of 
products  for  reserve;  stocks  of  wheat,  sugar,  whale  oil,  and  other 
materials  haA-e  already  been  purchased. 

International . — An' agreement  for  tlie  control  of  coke  exports,  both 
in  volume  and  in  price,  was  entered  into  by  producers  in  tlie  United 


2g0  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 

Kingdom,  Germany,  Holland,  Belgium,  Poland,  and  Danzig,  in  June 
1937,  effective  for  3  years,  with  administration  by  an  international 
association  office  in  Brussels.  The  international  tin  agreement  was 
renewed  for  a  5-year  period  beginning  January  1,  1937.  The  mercury 
agreement  was  terminated  in  December  1936,  due  to  war  conditions  in 
Spain.  The  European  zinc  cartel  was  reformed,  comprising  manufac- 
turers in  Great  Britain.  Belgium,  Holland,  Germany,  Poland,  Austria, 
and  Czechgslovakia.  An  agreement  entered  into  in  October  1937  by 
buyers  of  cacao  in  West  Africa,  whereby  a  pool  should  be  formed  to 
buy  at  an  agreed  price,  resulted  in  a  boycott  by  Gold  Coast  farmers, 
and  the  pool  agreement  was  suspended  until  October  1938.  An  im- 
portant report  on  the  possibility  of  obtaining  a  general  reduction  in 
the  obstacles  to  international  trade  was  prepared  by  M.  Paul  Van  Zee- 
land,  of  Belgium,  upon  request  of  the  Governments  of  England  and 
France,  and  was  printed  as  a  British  White  Paper  in  January  1938. 

The  United  States  entered  into  a  reciprocal  trade  agreement  with 
Czechoslovakia  on  March  7,  1938,  effective  on  April  16,  1938. 

Iran. — An  agricultural  act  was  passed  on  November  16,  1937,  for 
setting  up  a  program  to  increase  production,  reclaim  and  improve 
lands,  repair  buildings  and  roads,  and  finance  agricultural  proj- 
ects. 

Italy. — Interest  is  centered  primarily  upon  the  activities  of  the 
guilds,  to  which  have  been  assigned  the  duties  of  regulating  prices 
and  wages,  authorizing  the  opening  of  new  plants  or  the  enlarge- 
ment of  those  in  existence,  regulating  investments,  and  planning 
economic  policies  with  a  view  to  increasing  the  national  wealth. 

/a;?6m.— Legislation  in  Japan  in  1937  and  1938  increasing  govern- 
mental authority  over  industry  and  trade,  included :  The  temporary 
fund  adjustment  law,  controlling  new  industrial  investments  which 
has  been  applied  to  a  number  of  industries,  namely,  airplanes,  metal 
production  machinery,  munitions,  steel  ships,  iron  and  steel,  gold, 
coal,  and  petroleum;  the  emergency  import  and  export  control  law, 
authorizing  the  Government  to  control  imports  and  exports,  produc- 
tion, distribution,  and  consumption  of  commodities,  during  the  Sino- 
Japanese  hostilities  and  for  a  year  after  their  termination;  the  ship 
control  law ;  the  law  concerning  emergency  rice  measures  to  replenish 
stocks  of  Government-owned  rice;  tlie  fertilizer  distribution  control 
law;  the  application  .of  armament  industries  mobilization  law;  the 
imperial  fuel  investment  company  law;  the  iron  and  steel  industry 
law,  which  contemplates  doubling  the  output  of  the  mills,  effecting 
compulsory  extension  of  plants  and  furnaces,  and  granting  to  new 
plants  exemption  from  taxation  for  a  period  of  10  years;  the  Gold 
Mining  Act  of  August  10,  1937,  providing  for  regulation  of  mining 
activities  and  the  sale  of  ores,  under  a  license  plan,  with  subsidies 
to  miners  and  refiners;  the  China  incident  taxation  law;  and  the 
antiprofiteering  amendment  law,  which  revived  an  ordinance  issued 
in  1917  in  prevention  of  price  increase.  Measures  adopted  in  October 
1937  placed  all  stages  of  the  cotton  industry  under  state  control.  An 
imperial  ordinance  on  May  7,  1938,  provided  for  a  Materials  Adjust- 
ment Bureau  to  adjust  the  supply  and  demand  of  important  materials, 
including  iron  and  steel,  other  metals,  coal,  machinery,  fibers,  chemi- 
cals, and  articles  in  foreign  trade.  Price  committees  will  enforce  offi- 
cial quotations  and  standard  prices. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEJR  281 

Latvia. — Under  the  chambers  of  commerce  and  industry  law  of  1934, 
state  control  of  industrial  activities  has  been  extended  to  cover  many 
important  productive  lines,  including  railways,  airplanes,  telephones, 
and  r^dio  service,  hydroelectric  power,  forest  lands,  sugar,  flax,  grain, 
wool  fabrics,  confectionery,  alcohol,  beer,- tobacco,  refined  oil,  cellulose, 
plywood,  iron  and  steel  products,  wire,  bricks,  lime,  peat,  and  films. 
The  state  also  owns  the  Bank  of  Latvia,  a  number  of  credit  institu- 
tions, two  resort  hotels,  a  life  insurance  company,  a  shipping  company, 
and  a  travel  bureau.  Special  attention  is  given  to  export  commodities, 
such  as  butter,  seeds,  flax,  and  lumber.  Plants  for  the  packing  and 
export  of  bacon,  hams,  butter,  and  eggs,  have  been  erected  under  state 
control.  A  price  inspector  has  authority  to  supervise  the  production 
of  all  merchandise  and  to  regulate  prices  in  all  lines  of  trade  and 
industry,  including  housing-.  The  value  of  state-owned  property  is 
estimated  at  one-third  of  the  national  wealth. 

Mamchukuo. — The  law  for  the  confrol  of  important  industries  ef- 
fective on  May  10,  1937,  gave  wide  power  over  industries  designated 
as  important,  of  which  more  than  20  have  been  named;  changes  in 
equipment  or  production,  and  any  agreements  relating  to  production, 
price,  or  sales,  must  be  approved  by  the  government  An  emergency 
trade  control  law  was  passed  in  June  1937,  for  protecting  agricultural 
products,  adjusting  internal  prices,  and  controlling  imports.  A  for- 
eign trade  control  law  passed  in  December  1937,  went  further  toward 
adjustment  of  supply  and  demand.  An  iron  and  steel  control  law 
became  effective  on  April  1,  1938. 

Mexico. — In  addition  to  the  program  of  land  distribution  and  the 
organization  of  rural  communities  for  collective  farming  under  Gov- 
ernment supervision,  a  number  of  important  decrees  were  issued  in 
1937,  including  decrees  in  June  1937,  for  control  of  the  silk  and 
artificial  silk  industries,  providing  also  that  imports  of  certain  tex- 
tile materials  and  thread,  and  machinery  for  knitting  and  weaving 
thereof,  shall  be  placed  under  license  control  by  the  Department  of 
National  Economy;  a  decree  effective  on  June  24,  1937,  for  expro- 
priation of  the  railways  (under  the  expropriation  law  of  November 
23,  1936)  ;  a  decree  effective  on  June  25,  1937,  establishing  control  of 
production,  importation,  distribution,  and  prices  of  all  commodities 
which  may  be  declared  to  be  of  fundamental  importance  and  re- 
quiring the  formation  of  State  producers'  associations  and  national 
producers'  unions;  a  decree  under  which  a  foreign  trade  bank  was 
set  up  on  June  18,  1937,  and  a  workers'  bank  in  July,  to  finance 
syndicates  of  employees  and  small  merchants  and  manufacturers ;  and 
in  August  1937,  a  decree  authorizing  creation  of  a  Federal  elec- 
trical commission  to  organize  and  administer  a  national  system  of 
electric  generation,  transmission,  and  distribution.  A  petroleum 
council  was  formed  in  March  1938,  to  administer  property  expro- 
priated from  the  petroleum  companies. 

NetJierlands.—k.  law  effective  on  April  8,  1937,  authorized  the 
Minister  of  Commerce^  Industry,  and  Shipping  to  control  and  limit 
new  operators  of  retail  business,  trade,  and  small  industries.  This 
was  supplemented  by  the  industrial  establishment  law  passed  in 
March  1938,  for  the  control  of  new  industrial  enterprises  or  the  in- 
crease in  capacity  of  those  already  established. 

Decree  of  the  Governor  General  of  Netherlands  Indies,  dated  De- 
cember 30,  1937,  extended  for  an  indefinite  period  the  industrial 


282  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

control  ordinance  of  1934,  which  has  been  applied  to  a  number  of 
industries,  including  dairies,  metal  foundries,  the  cigarette  industry, 
ice  factories,  storage  warehouses,  the  printing  industry,  the  weaving 
industry,  and  native  rubber  smokehouses. 

New  Zealand. — The  primary  products  marketing  amendment  bill 
presented  to  the  Parliament  in  December  1937,  would  empower  the 
Marketing  Department  to  fix  maximum  and  minimum  wholesale  and 
retail  prices  for  dairy  produce,  fruit,  honey,  eggs,  and  other  food- 
stuifs  prescribed  by  order  in  council,  and  to  buy  foodstuffs  at  fixed 
prices,  exporting  the  surplus  over  home  requirements. 

A  law  passed  on  March  15,  1938,  provided  for  establishment  of  an 
iron  and  steel  monopoly,  under  Government  operation,  utilizing  do- 
mestic deposits  of  iron  ore,  and  constructing  new  works  for  manufac- 
turing purposes.  Prior  to  this,  iron  and  steel  products  have  been 
imported,  largely  from  the  United  Kingdom  and  Australia. 

Newfoundland. — The  act  to  amend  and  consolidate  the  law  relating 
to  the  customs  and  excise,  dated  March  26,  1938,  included  provisions 
for  valuation  of  goods  for  duty  purposes,  and  also  in  case  of  imports 
at  prices  or  values  involving  unfair  competition  with  producers  or 
manufacturers  in  the  British  Empire. 

Nyasaland  {Central  Africa). — Under  the  tobacco  marketing  law, 
December  21,  1937,  all  fire-cured  leaf  tobacco  grown  in  the  country 
must  be  marketed  through  licensed  auction  warehouses,  under  a 
tobacco  control  board. 

Panama. — A  decree  in  .938  required  that  fixed  charges  (retail 
prices)  must  be  asked  foi  all  merchandise  offered  for  sale.  Each 
article  must  bear  a  tag  showing  the  sales  price  to  be  observed  by 
all  stores. 

Peru. — A  decree  of  June  17,  1937,  required  all  commercial  organi- 
zations to  report  to  the  Government  in  January  and  July  of  each 
year,  declaring  all  raw  nuaterial  handled  by  them  in  their  business 
undertakings. 

Portugal. — Law  No.  1957,  May  20,  1937,  placed  Portuguese  agri- 
culture under  direct  supervision  and  control  of  the  state,  to  be  ef- 
fected through  corporate  organizations  or  guilds  which  will  be 
authorized  to  promote  the  sale  and  marketing  of  farm  products,  and 
to  enforce  regulations  laid  down  by  the  state  for  the  protection  of 
the  national  economy.  The  guilds  also  may  own  and  operate  stores, 
granaries,  agricultural  machinery,  and  livestock,  and  install  various 
services  for  the  common  interest  of  the  members. 

Rhodesia.,  Southern. — The  Customs  and  Excise  Amendment  Act  of 
May  18,  1937,  repeats  the  antidumping  provisions  of  the  act  of  1935. 

South  Africa.,  Union  of. — Marketing  Act  No.  26,  1937,  provides 
for  voluntary  regulation  of  the  production  and  sale  of  agricultural 
products,  establishment  of  certain  regulatory  boards,  the  grading  and 
standardization  of  agricultural  products,  and  other  matters  incidental 
thereto. 

Spain. — The  Government  has  set  up  a  committee  to  buy  all  the  raw 
wool  produced  in  the  country  and  to  take  over  imports,  which  will 
be  placed  at  the  disposal  of  the  spinning  industry.  The  purpose  is 
said  to  be  to  reduce  the  price  of  wool  and  to  prevent  undue  increase 
in  the  price  of  manufactured  goods.  A  tobacco  monopoly  has  been 
created  to  regulate  the  production,  importation,  manufacture,  and 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR  283 

distribution  of  tobacco,  matches,  and  lighters.  The  production  of 
raw  tobacco  will  be  increased,  manufacturing  plants  may  not  be  shut 
down  or  opened  without  governmental  consent,  and  prices  to  be  paid 
to  the  growers  will  be  fixed  by  the  Government. 

Sweden. — In  an  effort  to  strengthen  the  Government's  control  over 
prices  and  money  market,  a  number  of  laws  were  passed  in  1937: 
extending  authorization  of  the  National  Debt  Office  to  furnish  the 
Riksbank  with  treasury  bills  or  other  state  bonds,  for  sale  in  the 
open  market ;  authorizing  the  Government  to  issue  special  regula- 
tions concerning  the  cash  reserves  of  commercial  banks;  appropria- 
tion of  70,000,000  crowns  to  purchase  commodities  for  storage;  in- 
crease of  the  stamp  tax  on  the  transfer  of  shares,  effective  to  May  31, 
1938,  and  release  of  the  Riksbank  from  its  obligation  to  redeem  its 
notes  in  gold,  extended  to  February  28,  1938. 

Turkey. — Law  No.  3003,  1937,  authorized  the  Minister  of  Economy 
to  control  and  fix  the  wholesale  and  retail  prices  of  industrial  prod- 
ucts where  he  considers  such  action  necessary,  and  to  make  all 
inquiries  requisite  for  the  purpose. 

Uruguay. — Decree  of  October  21,  1937,  provided  for  control  of 
retail  sales  prices  of  pharmaceutical  specialties  and  dietetic  products, 
in  order  to  safeguard  the  public  health  and  also  to  prevent  unduly 
high  retail  prices. 


EXHIBIT  10 

PART  V.  FOREIGN-TRADE  WORK 

Excerpts  From  Annual,  Report  of  the  Federal.  Trade  Commission 
FOR  the  Fiscal  Year  Ending  June  30,  1939 

The  Export  Trade  Act.  Supplemental  Report  on  Antidump- 

Exported  Goods  Valued  at  $161,244,820.  ing  Legislation. 

Forty-three  Export  Associations  on  File.  Trust  Laws  and  Unfair  Competition 

Services  Rendered  by  the  Associations.  Abroad. 

Advantages  Obtained  by  the  Associations. 

Foreign-trade  work  of  the  Commission  includes  administration  of 
the  Export  Trade  Act  (Webb-Pomerene  law)  and  inquiries  under 
section  6  (h)  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act,  by  the  Export 
Trade  Section,  under  direction  of  the  chief  counsel. 

THE  export  trade  ACT 

The  Export  Trade  Act,  approved  April  10,  1918,  provides  that  the 
Sherman  Antitrust  Act  shall  not  be  construed  as  declaring  to  be  illegal 
an  association  (which  may  be  a  corporation  or  a  combination  of  two  or 
more  persons,  partnerships,  or  corporations)  engaged  solely  in  export 
trade  or  an  agreement  or  act  of  such  an  association  in  the  course  of 
export  trade ;  provided  that  any  such  association,  agreement,  or  act  is 
not  in  restraint  of  trade  within  the  United  States  or  in  restraint  of  the 
export  trade  of  any  domestic  competitor  of  such  association,  and  that 
such  an  association  does  not,  in  the  United  States  or  elsewhere,  enter 
into  any  agreement  or  conspiracy  or  do  any  act  which  artificially  or 
intentionally  enhances  or  depresses  prices  within  the  United  States  or 
substantially  lessens  competition  within  the  United  States.  Organ- 
ization papers  and  further  reports  are  filed  with  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission. 

exported  goods  valued  at  $161,244,820  IN  1938 

Total  exports  by  Webb-law  groups  have  varied  from  a  low  point  of 
$91,180,000  in  1921  to  a  high  point  of  $724,100,000  in  1929  (including  in 
that  ^ear  the  petroleum  associations  since  dissolved  and  the  copper 
associations  not  now  active).  Exports  in  1937  totaled  $197,875,832; 
and  in  1938,  $161,244,820. 

The  associations  may  be  roughly  divided  into  five  groups : 
1.  Associations  exporting  metals  and  metal  products  and  machinery. 
These  now  include  steel  products,  metal  lath,  pipe  fittings  and  valves, 
screws,  electrical  apparatus,  railway  signal  apparatus,  railway  steel 
springs  and  tires,  and  there  is  also  a  copper  association  not  now  in 
operation.  This  group  of  10  associations  now  represents  67  companies 
shipping  to  foreign  countries.  Exports  by  this  class  have  varied  in 
value  from  the  high  point  of  $271,000,000  in  1929  (which  included  cop- 
284 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEiR  285 

per  exports)  to  the  lowest  figure  of  $20,250,000  in  1935.     The  total  in 
1937  was  $93,958,850;  and  in  1938,  $67,000,000. 

2.  Exporters  of  products  of  mines  and  wells,  including  phosphate 
rock,  sulfur,  carbon  black,  and  potash.  At  one  time  this  group  in- 
cluded petroleum  companies,  since  dissolved.  In  the  5  associations 
now  operating,  24  companies  are  represented.  Exports  under  this 
classification  have  varied  from  a  high  point  of  $315,000,000  in  1930 
(including  petroleum  exports)  to  a  low  point  of  $5,556,000  in  1921. 
Their  exports  in  1937  totaled  $32,580,219 ;  and  in  1938,  $20,920,491. 

3.  Exporters  of  lumber  and  wood  products — pine,  fir,  redwood,  hard- 
Avood,  walnut,  plywood,  barrel  and  box  shooks,  tool  handles,  and  naval 
stores.  There  are  now^  9  associations  representing  140  mills,  scattered 
from  coast  to  coast.  Exports  of  lumber  and  wood  products  in  1925 
totaled  $38,000,000;  this  dropped  to  $8,000,000  in  1932.  The  total  in 
1937  was  $7,456,922;  and  in  1938,  $5,881,028.  Some  of  this  decrease 
has  been  due  to  depletion  of  pine  forests  in  the  Southern  States. 

4.  Exporters  of  food  products.  Associations  now  operating  export 
meat  products,  canned  milk,  fruit,  rice,  and  sugar.  The  9  associations 
represent  101  companies.  Exports  of  foodstuffs  by  Webb-law  groups 
have  varied  from  a  high  point  of  $80,400,000  in  1928  to  a  low  point  of 
$5,839,000  in  1921.  The  total  for  1937  was  $19,921,343,  and  in  1938, 
$21,487,274. 

5.  Exporters  of  miscellaneous  manufactures,  such  as  paper,  textiles, 
rubber  products,  abrasives,  chemicals,  and  glass.  The  10  associations 
in  this  group  now  represent  93  companies  producing  these  goods  for 
export  trade.  Total  exports  under  this  classification  have  run  from 
$2,334,000  in  1921  to  $90,000,000  in  1929,  $43,958,498  in  1937,  and 
$45,956,027  in  1938. 

The  Webb  law  association  lists  show  some  changes  each  year.  ^  The 
number  of  associations  has  varied  from  43  in  1920  to  a  high  point  of 
57  from  1929  to  1931.  It  dropped  during  the  depression  years  to  43 
in  1935.  45  in  1936  and  1937,  44  in  1938,  and  again  43  in  1939. 

There  are  four  associations  that  have  been  in  operation  since  1918, 
the  first  year  that  the  law  was  passed.  These  are  the  American  Paper 
Exports,' Douglas  Fir  Export  Co.,  Redwood  Export  Co.,  and  the  Wal- 
nut Export  Sales  Co.  Seven  associations  have  been  in  operation  since 
1919,  just  20  years:  The  American  Provisions  Export  Co.,  Ameri- 
can Soda  Pulp  Export  Association,  Florida  Hard  Rock  Phosphate 
Export  Association.  General  Milk  Co.  (at  first  called  the  American 
Milk  Products  Corporation),  Phosphate  Export  Association,  Pipe 
Fittings  &  Valve  Export  Association,  and  the  U.  S.  Alkali  Export 
Association.  The  first  steel  association  operated  from  1919  to  1923; 
the  second  steel  group,  Steel  Export  Association  of  America,  has  been 
in  operation  since  1928.  The  first  copper  group  was  also  formed  in 
1919  and  operated  until  1933.  The  second  copper  group,  Copper 
Exporters,  Inc.,  was  formed  in  1926  and  is  still  filing  papers, 
although  not  in  active  operation.  The  rubber  and  sulfur  groups  were 
formed  in  1922.  the  petroleum  associations  in  1929,  the  textile  group 
in  1930,  and  the  electrical  association  in  1931.  Other  groups  have 
been  organized,  some  each  year,  as  listed  in  the  Commission's  annual 
reports. 

The  following  associations  were  formed  during  the  fiscal  year  ended 
June  30, 1939 :  Potash  Export  Association,  Inc.,  comprising  the  Ameri- 
can Potash  &  Chemical  Corporation,  U.  S.  Potash  Co.,  and  Potash 


286 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Co.  of  America,  with  headquarters  in  New  York ;  and  the  International 
Wood  Naval  Stores  Export  Corporation,  comprising  the  Chemical 
Products  Co.,  Continental  Turpentine  &  Kosin  Corporation,. Phoenix 
Naval  Stores  Co.,  Dixie  Pine  Products  Co.,  Crosby  Naval  Stores,  Inc., 
Southern  Naval  Stores  Co.,  Alabama  Naval  Stores  Co.,  and  Mackie 
Pine  Products  Co.,  with  headquarters  at  Gulfport,  Miss. 

43  EXPORT  ASSOCIATIONS  ON  FILE  JUNE  30.  1939 

At  the  close  of  the  fiscal  year,  June  30,  1939,  43  export  associations 
were  on  file  with  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  under  the  Export 
Trade  Act,  representing  425  mills,  mines,  factories,  and  producers 
scattered  throughout  the  United  States,  from  coast  to  coast,  shipping 
American  products  to  all  corners  of  the  globe : 


American  Box  Shook  Export  Associa- 
tion, Barr  Building,  Washington, 
D.  C. 

American  Hardwood  Exporters,  Inc., 
Carondelet  Building,  New  Orleans. 

American  Paper  Exports,  Inc.,  75  West 
Street,  New  York. 

American  Provisions  Export  Co.,  80 
East  Jackson  Boulevard,  Chicago. 

American  Soda  Pulp  Export  Associa- 
tion, 230  Park  Avenue,  New  York. 

American  Spring  Manufacturers  Ex- 
port Assocation,  30  Church  Street, 
New  York. 

American  Tire  Manufacturers  Export 
Association,  30  Church  Street,  New 
York. 

California  Alkali  Export  Association, 
523  West  Sixth  Street,  Los  Angeles. 

California  Dried  Fruit  Export  Associa- 
tion, 1  Drumm  Street,  San  Francisco. 

California  Prune  Export  Association, 
1  Drumm  Street,  San  Francisco. 

Carbon  Black  Export,  Inc.,  500  Fifth 
Avenue,  New  York. 

Cement  Export  Co.,  Inc.,  The,  150 
Broadway,  New  York. 

Copper  Exporters,  Inc.,  50  Broad\,ay, 
New  York. 

Douglas  Fir  Export  Co.,  Henry  Build- 
ing. Seattle. 

Durex  Abrasives  Corporation,  68  Wall 
Street,  New  York. 

Electrical  Apparatus  Export  Associa- 
tion, 70  Pine  Street,  New  York. 

Export  Screw  Association  of  the  United 
States,  23  Acorn  Street,  Providence, 
R.  I. 

Florida  Hard  Rock  Phosphate  Export 
Association,  Savannah  Bank  and 
Trust  Building,  Savannah,  Ga. 

General  Milk  Co.,  Inc.,  19  Rector 
Street,  New  York. 

Goodyear  Tire  &  Rubber  Export  Co., 
The,  1144  East  Market  Street,  Akron, 
Ohio. 

Grapefruit  Distributors,  Inc.,  Daven- 
port, Fla. 


International  Wood  Naval  Stores  Ex- 
port Corporation,  Gulfport,  Miss. 

Metal  Lath  Export  Association,  The,  47 
West  Thirty-fourth  Street,  New 
York. 

Northwest  Dried  Fruit  Export  Associa- 
tion, Title  &  Trust  Building,  Port- 
land,   Oreg. 

Pacific  Forest  Industries,  Tacoma 
Building,  Tacoma,  Wash. 

Pacific  Fre.sh  Fruit  Export  Association, 
333  Pine  Street,  San  Francisco. 

Phosphate  Export  Association,  393  Sev- 
enth Avenue,  New  York. 

Pipe  Fittings  and  Valve  Export  Asso- 
ciation, The,  1421  Chestnut  Street, 
Philadelphia. 

Plate  Glass  Export  Corporation,  Grant 
Building,  Pittsburgh. 

Potash  Export  Association,  Inc.,  21 
East  Fortieth  Street,  New  York. 

Redwood  Export  Co.,  405  Montgomery 
Street,   San  Francisco. 

Rice  Export  Association,  Queen  and 
Crescent  Building,  New  Orleans. 

Rubber  Export  Association,  The,  19 
Goodyear  Avenue,  Akron,  Ohio. 

Shook  Exporters  Association,  301  Mar- 
garet  Street,   Pekin,   111. 

Signal  Export  Association,  420  Lex- 
ington Avenue,  New  York. 

Steel  Export  Association  of  America, 
the,  75  West  Street,  New  York. 

Sugar  Export  Corporat'  j,  120  WalJ 
Street,  New  York. 

Sulphur  Export  Corporation,  420  Lex- 
ington Avenue,  New  York. 

Textile  Export  Association  of  the 
United  States,  40  Worth  Street,  New 
York. 

United  States  Alkali  Export  Associa- 
tion, Inc.,  11  Broadway,  New  York. 

United  States  Handle  Export  Co.,  the, 
Piqua,  Ohio. 

Walnut  Export  Sales  Co.,  Inc.,  Twelfth 
Street  and  Kaw  River,  Kansas  City, 
Kans. 

Walworth  International  Co.,  60  East 
Forty-second  Street,  New  York 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EXX)NOMIC  POWER  287 

SERA^CES  RENDERED  BY  THE  ASSOCIATIONS 

Each  Webb-law  association  is  formed  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  par- 
ticular industry  to  be  served.  There  is,  therefore,  considerable  variance 
in  the  functions  adopted.  Most  of  the  groups  have  become  incor- 
porated for  their  own  convenience,  although  the  law  does  not  requii^ 
it.  Most  of  them  operate  on  an  expense  basis,  the  profits  accruing  to 
the  individual  members. 

Some  associations  purchase  the  members'  products  for  the  purpose  of 
selling  them  to  foreign  buyers  at  terms  agreed  upon  by  the  members. 
Others  serve  as  central  selling  agents  for  the  members  taking  orders, 
negotiating  sales,  and  handling  the  shipment  of  the  goods.  In  some 
cases,  the  member  companies  negotiate  the  sales  under  direction  of  the 
association.  Offices  are  maintained  and  agents  emploj'ed  in  this  coun- 
try and  abroad.  Special  agents  are  appointed  to  exploit  the  members' 
products  in  new  markets.  Joint  advertising  and  joint  trade-marks  are 
used,  or  the  members'  brands  and  patented  goods  promoted. 

The  members  may  agree  upon  price,  terms,  and  sales  policies  solely 
for  export  shipment,  adopting  uniform  contracts.  In  some  cases  a 
minimum  price  is  agreed  upon;  in  others  members  are  free  to  quote 
price  but  agree  to  report  to  the  association  any  change  in  price.  More 
often  the  price  is  finally  determined  by  the  foreign  agent  of  the  asso- 
ciation, varying  in  different  markets  to  meet  the  local  conditions.  In 
this  connection,  it  may  be  of  interest  to  quote  from  a  report  recently 
received  from  a  well-established  association  which  has  been  in  active 
operation  for  a  number  of  years : 

The  establishment  of  prices  is  a  rlistinct  function  of  the  association. 
It  has  to  be  under  our  form  of  operation.  Prices  are  established  and  main- 
tained by  responsible  foreign  agents  over  whom  supervision  is  exercised  by  an 
association  otlicial  who  travels  abroad.  Prices  must  depend  upon  economic  con- 
ditions in  each  market  versus  maximum  consuming  power  of  that  market  under 
uormal  conditions.  In  other  words,  purchasing  power  is  an  important  factor 
to  be  considered  with  respect  to  maximum  sales.  Another  factor  is  competition  ; 
still  another  is  quality  and  a  study  of  the  needs  of  important  consumers  in  accord- 
ance with  their  processes  of  manufacturing.  Prices  necessarily  fluctuate  in  dif- 
ferent parts  of  the  world,  being  controlled  by  innumerable  conditions,  both  politi- 
cal and  economic.  In  some  instances  the  return  exceeds  domestic  levels  here; 
in  others  it  is  about  the  same ;  and  in  others  it  will  occasionally  dip  lower.  Con- 
sequently we  work  on  a  final  average  annual  price  for  export,  which  in  turn  is 
tributed  equitably  in  proportion  to  each  factory's  shipments. 

Credits  range  according  to  market  practices  and  the  standing  of  customers. 
Exchange  is  a  chapter  in  it.self.  There  is  the  problem  of  covering  future  ex- 
change, spot  exchange,  and  operating  with  no  exchange  whatsoever.  We  have  a 
free  movement  of  exchange,  semiembargoes  and  complete  embargoes.  This  in- 
volves much  in  the  way  of  difficult  financing. 

In  one  country  we  have  operated  at  a  maximum  of  1  year  without  securing  $1 
of  exchange,  allowing  our  funds  to  accumulate  and  eventually  liquidating  them 
thrfiugh  an  easement  in  exchange  regulations  over  a  period  of  a  year  thereafter. 
These  adversities  cause  much  in  the  loss  of  interest,  and  at  times  much  more  in 
depreciated  exchange,  when  available,  as  compared  to  the  I'ate  when  sales  were 
made.  Where  possible  we  cover  exchange  futures  as  far  in  advance  as  6  months  ; 
in  other  cases  local  trends  indicate  spot  coverage  over  different  periods;  again 
customers  have  been  permitted  to  hedge  exchange  and  provide  necessary  guaran- 
ties against  loss  in  our  acceptance  of  local  currency.  Sales  are  made  in  sterling 
to  markets  with  a  different  standard  of  currency- 
Constant  changes  in  foreign  tariffs  come  to  us  telegraphically  and  in  ample  time 
for  us  to  adopt  neces.sary  safeguards  by  advance  shipments  in  order  to  save  large 
sums  of  money. 

At  the  very  least,  a  maintained  price  level  can  return  from  20  to  .30  percent 
less  than  circumstances  seem  to  warrant,  and  even  reach  a  point  where  exports 


288  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

are  blocked  completely  over  certain  periods.  This  involves  heavy  stocking  of 
warehouses  abroad  in  advance,  increased  expenses,  and  uncertainty  regarding 
even  an  approximated  price  return. 

This  fact  alone  illustrates  the  tremendous  advantage  of  associated  activity  in 
contrast  to  individual  effort. 

Some  associations  divide  their  export  business  among  the  members 
in  predetermined  proportions,  or  quotas,  agreed  upon  by  the  members. 
For  this  purpose,  the  capital-stock  holdings  of  the  members  may  serve 
as  a  basis,  or  the  volume  of  export  business  over  some  past  period,  or 
perhaps  periodical  reports  by  the  members  as  to  amounts  available  for 
export.  Some  quota  systems  are  more  complicated,  including  consid- 
eration of  quality  as  well  as  quantity,  shipping  and  loading  facilities, 
iind  other  export  factors.  Provision  is  usually  made  for  readjustment 
of  quotas  to  meet  changing  conditions. 

Other  functions  that  have  been  adopted  by  the  export  associations 
include  standardizing  products  for  export  and  improving  the  quality 
of  the  goods ;  maintaining  inspection  service,  employing  claims  agents, 
and  settling  disputes  over  export  sales;  establishing  rules  and  regula- 
tions for  packing  and  shipping  the  goods ;  arranging  for  freight  rates, 
cargo  space,  and  shipping  dates;  consolidating  the  shipments  of  the 
members;  taking  out  insurance  and  shipping  documents;  providing  for 
storage  during  transit  and  warehousing  abroad ;  collecting  and  dissemi- 
nating trade  information  as  to  market  conditions  abroad,  foreign  cred- 
its, stocks  available  for  export,  exchange  problems,  tariff  requirements, 
shipping  rules  and  regulations,  foreign  laws  that  affect  our  foreign 
trade,  and  other  data  of  value  to  American  exporters. 

ADVANTAGES  OBTAINED  BY  THE  EXPORT  ASSOCIATIONS 

The  more  functions  the  association  adopts,  the  greater  economy  may 
be  effected  through  cooperative  action.  The  central  selling  agency  for 
all  members  operates  with  much  less  overhead  than  if  each  member 
company  were  selling  independently.  The  expense  of  exploitation  or 
development  of  new  markets  can  be  divided  among  all  the  members 
with  benefit  to  each.  The  association  may  fill  large  orders  by  drawing 
on  the  resources  of  the  members ;  and  by  pooling  the  shipments  may 
(jbtain  better  cargo  space  and  more  reasonable  transportation  rates. 
Agreement  upon  trade  practices  has  eliminated  abuses,  improved  rela- 
tions with  foreign  buyers,  and  reduced  claims  for  unsatisfactory 
shipments. 

The  association  is  in  a  position  to  obtain  for  its  members  information 
concerning  credits  and  market  conditions  abroad,  which  may  be  chang- 
'  ing  frequently ;  no  one  member  could  obtain  this  information  as  quickly 
or  with  as  little  expense. 

The  experience  of  the  associations,  in  actual  operation,  may  best  be 
shown  by  a  few  quotations  from  their  reports  to  this  office : 

One  of  the  first  lumber  groups  to  be  formed  reports  that — 

The  association  has  effected  orderly  merchandising  of  lumber  exports,  elim- 
inating unnecessary  competition,  and  providing  by  united  action  financial  support 
for  trade  development.  Standard  contracts  are  agreed  upon  with  uniform  terms 
and  conditions  of  sale.  Brands  are  standardized  ;  shipments  consolidated  ;  cargo 
space  arranged ;  insurance  handled ;  all  shipping  documents  prepared ;  effecting 
savings  in  export.  Market  reports  are  received  from  foreign  correspondents, 
credits  checked  through  reliable  sources,  exchange  abroad  and  tariffs  closely 
watched ;  sample  shipments  are  sent  abroad  in  the  development  of  business. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  289 

Another  lumber  group  reports : 

The  outstanding  advantage  of  operation  under  the  association  plan  lies  in  the 
ability  to  supply  the  foreign  markets  promptly  and  satisfactorily  by  drawing 
upon  the  entire  group  of  mills  through  a  central  organization  rather  than  depend- 
ing upon  each  unit,  the  most  of  which  under  normal  conditions  would  not  be  able 
to  furnish  a  full  cargo  of  export  lumber  at  one  loading.  As  it  is,  what  one  mill 
cannot  supply  is  readily  procured  from  another  and  the  export  markets  are 
supplied  promptly  and  uniformly. 

An  association  formed  to  ship  heavy-cargo  material  reports  the 
following  advantages  obtained  through  cooperative  action : 

Stabilized  export  prices  at  profitable  levels,  uniform  sales  terms,  standardiza- 
tion of  grades,  reduction  in  selling  expenses,  saving  on  ocean  freight,  saving  on 
insurance,  reduction  of  credit  losses,  elimination  of  unfair  claims  from  buyers, 
better  ability  to  meet  foreign  competition  in  the  export  field,  and  better  ability  to 
meet  centralized  buying  by  centralized  selling.  Only  by  combination  under  the 
Webb  law  and  acting  as  a  unit  can  the  American  producers  in  this  industry 
successfully  meet  the  competition  of  foreign  producers.  There  is  little  doubt, 
we  think,  that  if  the  American  producers  had  not  been  able  or  had  neglected  to 
take  full  advantage  of  the  provisions  of  the  Webb-Pomerene  law  to  combine  and 
make  a  joint  effort,  this  American  product  would  have  been  driven  out  of  foreign 
markets  many  years  ago. 

A  group  organized  to  ship  specialized  metal  products  reports  that: 

Success  of  this  company  as  a  Webb-Pomerene  organization  is  due  chiefly  to  the 
fact  that  we  have  gone  into  the  business  of  foreign  trade  in  what  we  feel  is  an 
intelligent  manner  and  have  followed  a  consistent  policy  year  in  and  year  out, 
in  good  times  and  in  poor  times,  of  maintaining  a  foreign  field  organization. 
Through  such  organization  we  have  been  enabled  to  build  up  and  maintain  a 
recognition  of  the  quality  of  our  brand.  This  quality  reputation,  together  with 
the  goodwill  created  by  tlie  maintenance  of  a  continued  foreign  sales  force,  has 
enabled  us  to  continue  to  .-ecure  bu.siness  even  in  the  face  of  foreign  price  com- 
wtition  of  a  Tery  serious  type. 

An  association  comprising  mills  scattered  tlirough  several  States  of 
the  Middle  West  gathers  its  members'  products  together  for  exporta- 
tion, and  reports  that: 

By  combining  the  resources  of  stocks,  experience,  etc.,  of  the  several  mills,  we 
at  one  time  redtice  the  costs  of  exporting  as  compared  with  individual  operation 
(cost  of  the  association  operation  is  estimated  as  about  one-fourth  of  the  previous 
costs  to  the  members)  ;  increase  the  ability  to  supply  practically  all  items  in  our 
line,  enjoy  the  effects  of  greater  prestige  in  the  foreign  markets,  and  control  in  a 
greater  measure  the  standards  of  measurement  and  quality. 

An  association  organized  in  1933  and  successful  even  in  the  depres- 
sion years,  reports : 

Formed  to  meet  chaos  in  prices,  terms,  and  conditions  of  sale  in  all  foreign 
markets  when  business  was  dull,  and  uneven  stability  when  business  was  good, 
the  association  is  now  the  exclusive  distributor  for  the  member  producers  in 
export  trade.  It  sells  on  a  miiform  contract  agreed  upon  and  guarantees  to  each 
producer  a  fixed  quota  of  the  association's  total  export  business,  also  agreed 
uiK)n.  Sales  are  made  to  distributors,  delivered  at  foreign  ports;  it  is,  therefore, 
able  to  effect  economies  in  consolidating  shipments,  arranging  freight  rates,  cargo 
space,  and  shipping  dates,  consolidating  insurance,  and  preparing  shipping  papers. 

An  association  shipping  food  products  since  1925  reports  that : 

Uniform  sales  terms  and  sound  trade  custopis  continue  to  be  outstanding  advan- 
tages of  association  operation.  The  association  was  formed  primarily  to  correct 
chaotic  conditions  which  had  arisen  in  this  industry  as  a  result  of  activities  of 
both  organized  and  unorganized  buying  factors  in  Europe.  The  association 
facilities  include  the  development  of  nniform  contracts  and  terms  of  sale,  the 
definition  of  trade  custom,  provision  for  inspection  of  goods  shipped  and  certifi- 
cation thereof,  arbitration,  and  promulgation  of  rules,  regulations,  and  policies 
relating  to  the  conduct  of  export  trade,  including  the  elimination  of  abuses. 


290  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 

The  association  offers  to  its  members  a  method  of  presenting  their 
claims  before  boards  and  conferences.     One  reports  that : 

During  negotiations  with  ttie  conferences  and  steamship  lines  this  associa- 
tion, particularly  this  year,  found  of  great  value  the  control  of  the  tonnage  ex- 
iwrted  by  its  different  members  and  was  able  to  obtain  a  satisfactory  ocean 
freight  rate  for  the  year  1939. 

Another  states  that  its  abilit;^  to  deal  with  large  purchasing  com- 
bines abroad  has  been  of  material  benefit.  Some  of  the  associations 
have  presented  data  to  the  United  States  Government  in  connection 
with  proposed  reciprocal  trade  treaties  that  could  only  have  been  com- 
piled by  cooperative  action. 

As  an  illustration  of  association  action  during  disturbed  conditions 
in  Europe  in  1938,  one  reports : 

We  were  able  to  take  advantage  early  in  the  year  of  strengthened  exchange 
abroad  and  improve  our  selling  prices  in  several  countries.  Later-  with  war 
clouds  on  the  horizon,  we  were  enabled  to  keep  careful  track  of  shipments  en 
route,  divert  them  to  different  ports  or  hold  them  in  warehouses  at  European 
ports  until  the  situation  cleared  and  we  could  complete  delivery.  Thus  no  credit 
losses  were  sustained  from  territories  which  were  taken  over  by  Germany. 

SUPPLEMENTAL  REPORT  ON  ANTIDUMPING  LEGISLATION 

Under  section  6  (h)  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act,  a  sup- 
plemental report  on  antidumping  legislation  and  other  import 
regulations  in  the  United  States  and  foreign  countries,  covering  the 
years  1934  to  1938,  was  presented  to  Congress  in  June  1938.  Copies 
are  now  available  for  distribution  upon  request. 

TRUST   LAWS    AND    UNFAIR    COMPETITION    IN    FOREIGN    COUNTRIES 

Also  under  section  6  (A),  the  Commission  follows  current  trust  legis- 
lation and  unfair  competition  in  foreign  countries.  The  following 
measures  are  noted : 

Algeria. — A  decree  in  1938  required  formation  of  syndicates  by  all 
commercial  producers  of  citrus  fruit  to  enforce  regulations  pertaining 
to  the  planting,  cultivation,  sale,  and  transportation  of  the  fruit.  The 
French  law  of  October  5,  1938,  noted  elsewhere  in  this  report,  is  appli- 
cable to  Algeria. 

Argeritina. — The  grain  board  was  reorganized  and  the  minimum 
price  guaranty  program  reestablished  under  laws  passed  in  September 
and  November  1938.  A  decree  on  December  8,  1938,  extended  the 
program  to  include  cattle,  under  administration  of  the  National  Meat 
Board.  Subsidies  paid  to  producers  of  grain  and  cattle  are  covered 
by  profits  from  control  of  exchange.  An  antidumping  bill  was  sent  to 
Congress  in  Septeipber  1938  but  failed  to  pass  before  adjournment  on 
September  30.  A  provincial  law  in  Buenos  Aires  in  1939  declared  the 
business  of  supplying  electric  current  a  public  service,  to  be  adminis- 
tered by  a  Bureau  of  Electric  Services. 

Australia. — The  Motor  Industry  Bounty  Act  and  the  Newsprint 
Paper  Bounty  Act  became  effective  in  December  1938.  The  bounty 
payable  on  exports  of  citrus  fruits  was  continued.  Under  a  plaii 
adopted  in  1938,  a  tax  will  be  levied  on  all  wheat  milled  for  consump- 
tion in  Australia ;  funds  derived  therefrom  will  be  used  to  make  up  the 
difference  between  the  export  price  and  the  domestic  price  if  the  latter 
is  maintained  above  world  prices. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  291 

Austria. — Under  a  decree  dated  July  14,  1938,  the  German  cartel 
legislation  was  introduced  in  Austria. 

Belgium. — In  September  1938  a  series  of  emergency  measures  were 
made  effective  to  safeguard  domestic  supplies  of  foodstuffs,  raw  mate- 
rials, and  other  necessities.  The  Minister  of  Economic  Affairs  was 
authorized  to  grant  export  permits,  to  prohibit  the  use  in  animal  feed- 
stuffs  of  any  products  that  might  serve  as  food  for  human  beings,  to 
inventory  stocks  of  merchandise  and  regulate  their  use,  and  to  regulate 
production,  manufacture,  and  distribution  of  products  for  human 
consumption, 

.  A  royal  decree  dated  January  18,  1939,  limited  the  period  of  special 
sales  in  the  retail  trade  in  order  to  protect  traders  and  consumers  from 
unfair  competition.  Another  decree,  March  22,  1939,  prolonged  au- 
thority of  the  Government  to  regulate  the  use  of  designations  under 
which  products  are  sold  in  commerce  when  the  interests  of  producers, 
distributors,  or  consumers  so  demand. 

Bolivia. — Under  a  constitution  adopted  in  October  1938,  all  mineral 
wealth,  public  lands,  and  their  natural  resources,  waters,  and  sources 
of  power  are  the  property  of  the  nation.  The  state  is  empowered  to 
regulate  commerce  and  industry  in  the  public  interest. 

Brazil. — The  Monopoly  Act,  No.  869  of  1938,  declared  violation 
thereof  a  criminal  offense,  punishable  by  fine  and  imprisonment.  No 
bail  will  be  allowed  and  no  pardon  or  conditional  freedom  granted. 
All  such  crimes  will  be  tried  before  the  Tribunal  of  National  Safety : 
Destruction  or  illegal  use  of  raw  material  or  products  necessary  for 
consumption  of  the  people ;  abandonment  of  tilled  land  or  the  closing 
of  factories  in  return  for  payment  to  restrain  competition;  promotion 
or  participation  in  combinations  or  agreements  to  restrain  competitors 
in  material  used  in  production,  transportation,  or  commerce,  for  the 
purpose  of  increasing  profits;  retaining  or  monopolizing  raw  material, 
means,  or  production,  of  products  necessary  for  the  consumption  of 
the  people,  for  the  purpose  of  dominating  the  market  and  causing 
increase  in  prices;  selling  merchandise  below  cost  price  for  the  purpose 
of  restraining  competitors;  using  false  news,  fictitious  operations,  or 
other  fraudulent  means  to  increase  or  decrease  prices,  the  value  of 
public  bonds,  articles  of  value,  or  salaries;  the  use  of  false  indications 
or  statements  in  the  sale  of  bonds  or  shares;  interlocking  directorates 
or  officers  of  companies  in  the  same  line  of  business  for  the  purpose  of 
restraining  competitors;  operating  fraudulently  banks,  banking  and 
capitalization  societies,  insurance  companies,  savings  banks,  mutual 
benefit  societies,  aid  and  pension  societies,  or  cooperative  societies,  by 
causing  their  bankruptcy  or  insolvency,  or  by  breach  of  contract  result- 
ing in  loss  to  interested  parties;  fraudulent  entries,  registration,  or 
reports  for  the  purpose  of  concealing  profits,  dividends,  or  percentages, 
or  the  fraudulent  use  of  reserve  funds;  entering  into  agreements  to 
impose  a  resale  price  or  demand  that  the  buyer  shall  not  purchase  from 
another;  departure  from  official  prices  of  merchandise;  attempting  to 
obtain  illicit  gain  by  fraudulent  processes  such  as  "chains,"  etc. ;  vio- 
lation of  contracts  of  sale  or  installmfents,  cheating  in  the  drawing  of 
lots,  failing  to  deliver  without  return  of  the  installments  paid,  in  case 
of  a  contract  rescinded  by  the  buyer;  fraudulently  tampering  with 
weights  or  measures  standardized  by  law ;  and  usurious  practices  such 
as  charging  interest  in  excess  of  that  permitted  by  law,  or  obtaining 

2'776il— 41 — No.  G -20 


292  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 

a  profit  exceeding  one-fifth  of  the  current  or  fair  value  of  the  install- 
ment made  or  promised. 

Under  a  presidential  decree  of  December  15,  1938,  flour  mills  will 
be  required  to  purchase  home-gi"own  wheat  at  a  fixed  price  and  in 
quantities  to  be  determined  on  a  quota  basis.  Imports  will  be  limited, 
and  the  Government's  efforts  to  increase  wheat  production  to  the  point 
of  self-sufficiency  will  be  continued. 

Canada. — The  Canadian  Grain  Act  was  amended  on  April  7,  1938. 
The  Dominion  Government  submitted  to  Parliament  in  April  1939  a 
report  presenting  a  new  wheat-marketing  policy  in  the  form  of  a  crop- 
insurance  plan.  To  facilitate  the  plan  bills  have  been  introduced  for 
the  regulation  of  the  Winnipeg  Grain  Exchange  and  the  encourage- 
ment of  cooperative  marketing ;  the  wheat  board  would  operate  as  a 
central  selling  agency  for  cooperative  organizations. 

The  Dairy  Industry  Act,  Farmers'  Creditors  Arrangement  Act  of 
1934,  and  the  Seeds  Act  of  1937  were  amended  on  July  1,  1938.  An  act 
to  assist  the  Provinces  of  Alberta  and  Saskatchewan  in  financing  the 
cost  of  seed  and  seeding  operations  for  the  crop  year  1938  was  passed 
on  April  7,  1938.  An  act  to  assist  in  the  alleviation  of  unemployment 
and  agricultural  distress,  supplemental  to  acts  passed  in  1936  and 

1937,  was  passed  on  May  25,  1938. 

An  act  to  regulate  the  inspection  and  sale  of  binder  twine  and  to 
establish  weight  of  bushel  for  certain  commodities  was  passed  on  June 
24,  1938;  the  inspection  and  sale  act  of  1927  was  repealed.  The  Food 
and  Drugs  Act  was  amended  on  April  5, 1939,  and  the  Meat  and  Canned 
Foods  Act  on  May  2,  1939.  The  Kadio  Act  of  July  1,  1938,  provided 
for  regulation  of  broadcasting  stations.    The  Transport  Act,  July  1, 

1938,  created  a  Board  of  Transport  Commissioners  to  regulate  trans- 
portation by  railways,  ships,  and  aircraft.  The  Shipping  Act  of  1934 
was  amended  on  June  24,  1938. 

Under  the  Combines  Investigation  Act,  report  was  issued  on  August 
31,  1938,  on  an  inquiry  into  an  alleged  combine  in  the  distribution  of 
tobacco  products.  The  Combines  Commission  found  that  retailers  and 
wholesalers  had  been  refused  supplies  for  the  purpose  of  maintaining 
fixed  prices  and  monopolistic  trade  restrictions,  resale  price  mainte- 
nance, certain  standardization  of  packaging,  and  other  uniform  trade 
practices,  had  contributed  to  a  lessening  of  price  competition.  As  a 
result  of  the  inquiry,  action  was  brought  under  section  498  of  the 
Criminal  Code  cliarging  monopoly  by  35  corporations  and  10  indi- 
viduals, including  manufacturers  and  wholesale  distributors  in  the 
tobacco  industry.  Hearings  were  held  in  the  superior  court  at  Edmon- 
ton in  April  1939;  the  case  was  to  be  continued  at  a  later  sitting  of 
the  court. 

A  report  by  the  Combines  Investigation  Commission  on  an  alleged 
combine  in  the  manufacture  and  sale  of  paperboard  shipping  contain- 
ers, was  submitted  on  March  14,  1939.  j  The  Commission  found  that 
two  combinations  had  operated  to  the  detriment  of  the  public  through 
a  series  of  written  agreements  under  which  prices  were  fixed  and  main- 
tained, and  a  system  of  sales  allotments  or  quotas  developed,  with  pen- 
alties imposed  if  a  member  sold  beyond  his  quota.  An  alleged  combine 
in  the  distribution  of  fruits  and  vegetables  in  western  Canada  is  now 
under  investigation  by  the  Commission. 

A  provincial  investigation  of  farm-implement  prices  and  distribu- 
tion resulted  in  a  report  by  a  legislative  committee  in  Saskatchewan 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  293 

in  1939.  Several  plans  were  proposed  to  bring  about  lower  prices  of 
agricultural  implements,  including  a  recommendation  for  prosecution 
under  the  Combines  Investigation  Act,  and  adoption  of  a  purchasing 
plan  through  a  cooperative  association  witli  Government  financial 
assistance.  A  provincial  law  was  passed  on  April  1,  1939,  authorizing 
the  Saskatchewan  Cooperative  Wholesale  Society,  Ltd.,  to  do  retail 
as  well  as  wholesale  business.  This  organization  might  be  used  to 
further  the  agricultural-implement  plan.  The  Saskatchewan  Cooper- 
ative Associations  Act  of  1930  was  also  revised  in  1939. 

A  Natural  Products  Marketing  Act,  passed  in  Manitoba  on  April  17, 
1939,  empowered  a  board  to  control  transportation,  packing,  storing, 
and  marketing  of  any  natural  product  within  the  Province.  Prices 
fixed  by  the  British  Columbia  Milk  Producers'  Clearing  House  Cooper- 
ative Association,  organized  as  a  selling  agency  under  the  Natural 
Products  Marketing  Act  of  that  Province,  were  attacked  in  the  courts 
in  1939.  An  injunction  issued  against  the  association  in  April  was  set 
aside  by  the  supreme  court  of  the  Province  in  May. 

Colombia. — A  law  passed  in  1938  provided  for  the  establishment 
of  plants  for  the  manufacture  of  iron  and  steel,  by  companies  in 
which  the  Government  may  hold  a  majority  of  the  capital  stock. 

Czechoslovak  Republic. — A  temporary  governmental  decree  effec- 
tive on  November  8,  1938,  provided  for  the  licensing  of  trades,  pro- 
fessions, and  industrial  enterprise.  Its  purpose  is  said  to  be  to  effect 
business  reorganization  in  the  State,  and  to  avoid  too  hasty  removal 
of  industries  from  Austria  and  the  Sudeten  region. 

Dominican  Republic. — A  decree  issued  on  November  7,  1938,  pro- 
vided for  the  regulation  of  production,  preparation,  and  marketmg 
of  rice. 

Ecuador. — Under  a  decree  of  July  8,  1938,  Government  regulation 
of  the  banana  industry  will  be  effected.  No  one  company  may  oAvn 
more  than  80,000  hectares  of  land;  holdings  in  excess  of  that  must 
be  disposed  of  to  Ecuadorans  within  5  years  or  they  will  become  the 
property  of  the  state  without  compensation.  Exportation  will  be 
supervised  by  the  Ministry  of   Social  Welfare. 

Egypt. — A  law  passed  on  August  1,  1938,  provided  regulatory  con- 
trol for  the  cultivation  of  cotton.  An  advisory  council  was  estab- 
lished on  December  18,  1938,  to  study  the  cotton  situation  and  assist 
in  formulating  a  policy.  Minimum  prices  have  been  fixed  and  short 
selling  discouraged.  Barter  agreements  with  other  countries,  and 
plans  for  collection  of  debts  owed  to  Egyptian  exporters  by  coun- 
tries with  currency  restrictions  are  under  consideration. 

Finland. — A  new  grain  law  effective  from  September  15,  1938,  to 
January  1944,  will  regulate  the  use  of  imported  wheat  and  rye. 

France. — A  law  dated  October  5,  1938,  authorized  the  Government 
to  issue  decrees  having  the  force  of  law,  and  to  take  measures  in- 
tended to  bring  about  the  immediate  economic  and  financial  rehabili- 
tation of  the  country.  A  number  of  decrees  have  been  issued.  The 
system  of  price  control  instituted  in  1937  has  been  modified.  Any 
increase  in  the  retail  price  of  goods  or  in  the  charges  for  services 
rendered  to  individuals,  above  existing  levels,  is  prohibited  unless 
authorized  by  price  supervisory  committees  (certain  food  and  perish- 
able goods  excepted).  Increase  in  the  wholesale  or  semi  wholesale 
price  of  industrial  products  may  be  prohibited  by  decree,  especially 
if  the  sales  are  made  through  cartel  organizations  or  under  agree- 


294  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWEH 

ments  between  producers,  including  international  agreements;  or  if 
the  goods  are  imported  and  subject  to  quota  regulations.  Decrees 
also  include  regulations  as  to  marking  of  prices  and  goodsoflfered  for 
retail  sale.  The  Government  is  authorized  to  raise  the  selling  prices 
of  monopoly  products  and  to  increase  direct  and  indirect  taxes 
in  order  to  adjust  them  to  present  prices  of  goods  and  services. 

A  law  on  March  19,  1939,  authorized  the  Government  to  issue  de- 
crees approved  by  the  Council  of  Ministers,  which  may  be  necessary 
for  the  defense  of  the  country.  A  decree  on  April  21,  1939,  limited 
profits  which  may  be  made  by  suppliers  of  materials  to  be  used  for 
tlie  national  defense;  the  Government  may  collect  certain  percentages 
of  profits,  varying  with  the  amounts  of  the  transactions. 

The  National  Economic  Council  issued  a  report  on  January  1, 
1939,  recommending  a  self-sufficient  agricultural  policy  covering  a 
list  of  farm  products  of  importance  in  France  and  its  possessions. 

Gernuiny. — A  law  dated  February  25,  1938,  provided  for  reorgan- 
ization of  the  Reich  Economic  Court,  and  transfer  to  it  of  the  func- 
tions of  the  German  Cartel  Court.  A  Reich  Committee  for  Increas- 
ing Industrial  and  Economic  Efficiency  has  been  established  by  the 
Minister  of  Economic  Affairs,  to  further  cooperation  between  the 
state  and  economic  organizations.  Numerous  orders  have  been  issued 
by  the  president  of  the  German  Trade  Development  Board  in  regu- 
lation of  commercial  advertising. 

Great  Britain. — The  Coal  Mines  Act  of  July  29,  1938,  strengthened 
provisions  of  the  act  of  1930  for  compulsory  amalgamations,  pro- 
vided for  the  purchase  and  administration  of  coal  royalties,  and  pro- 
longed to  December  1942  part  I  of  the  1950  law  which  was  the  legal 
basis  for  the  quota  system  and  selling  schemes. 

The  Prevention  of  Fraud  (Investments)  Act  of  April  28,  1939, 
added  to  blue-sky  laws  of  Britain,  further  provisions  intended  to  put 
a  stop  to  "share  pushing"  and  similar  fraudulent  practices  in  the 
sale  of  securities. 

The  Essential  Commodities  Reserves  Act,  passed  in  June  1938,  em- 
powered the  board  of  trade  to  obtain  from  traders,  information  as 
to  their  stocks  and  facilities  for  storing  commodities  essential  in  time 
of  war.  The  board  was  also  authorized  to  create  reserves  of  these 
products.  A  comprehensive  Ministry  of  Supplies  bill  was  presented 
to  Parliament  in  June  1939. 

The  Bacon  Industry  Act,  1938,  set  up  a  new  board  to  regulate  the 
sale  and  purchase  of  bacon  pigs,  guaranteeing  that  for  3  years  the 
price  shall  be  adjusted  to  differences  in  the  cost  of  feeding  stuffs,  and 
that  the  curer  shall  receive  a  standard  price. 

Administrative  powers  of  marketing  boards  and  schemes  under  the 
Agi-icultural  Marketing  Acts,  Coal  Mines  Act,  and  the  Herring  In- 
dustry Act,  are  considered  in  a  report  issued  in  1939  by  a  committee 
appointed  to  study  this  phase  of  regulation. 

The  Export  Guarantees  Act  of  1939  replaced  prior  laws  in  effect 
since  1920,  to  provide  export  credit  insurance. 

Greece. — Law  No.  1490,  passed  in  1938,  required  registration  of  ex- 
porters, prosecution  of  defaulting  exporters,  and  control  of  the  qual- 
ity of  exported  merchandise,  treating  adulteration  of  exported  goods 
as  a  criminal  offense. 


CONCE^-:SLATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  295 

Italy ^ — Under  wheat  and  flour  regulations,  in  1938,  the  service  of 
-delivery  of  grain  to  the  mills  is  under  control  of  the  Minister  of 
Corporations. 

ja'pwn. — A  commerce  and  industry  order  effective  on  July  9,  1938, 
provided  that  ordinances  may  be  issued  to  prohibit  increase  in  the 
price  of  articles  designated,  above  those  ruling  on  the  date  of  the 
order.  A  number  of  products  have  been  named.  A  far-reaching  pro- 
gram adopted  in  1939  by  the  Central  Price  Commission  will  include 
more  rigid  control  over  the  costs  of  raw  materials,  freight,  labor 
wages,  and  other  relating  cost  factors.  A  10-year  plan  has  been 
■announced  in  Taiwan  for  increase  in  agricultural  production  and 
•diversification  of  crops  other  than  rice. 

Latvia. — Under  a  law  passed  in  December  1938,  syndicates  are  to  be 
established  for  the  purpose  of  rationalizing  branches  of  trade  and  in- 
<lustry.  An  Institute  of  Economic  Research  will  make  recommenda- 
tions for  rationalization  plans. 

Mexico. — A  decree  published  August  12,  1938,  provided  for  a  Reg- 
ulatory Committee  for  the  Control  of  Commodities,  and  further  regu- 
lation of  the  supply,  distribution,  and  prices  of  the  necessities  of  life. 
Departments  will  Idc  formed  to  regulate  customs  tariffs,  taxes,  subsi- 
dies, transportation,  crop  credits,  clearing  houses,  produce  exchanges, 
and  other  factors  bearing  on  the  price  of  food.  When  necessary,  the 
committee  may  buy,  sell,  and  store  commodities  in  order  to  regulate 
the  price. 

Under  a  decree  of  October  4, 1938,  the  Government  may  fix  the  maxi- 
mum price  at  which'  sales  shall  be  made  to  consumers  in  the  country. 
There  are  also  production  groups  formed  under  the  Ministry  of  Na- 
tional Economy,  which  are  subject  to  instruction  as  to  their  produc- 
tion plans,  and  must  sell  through  a  central  organization.  The 
National  Commission  for  Foreign  Trade  has  been  directed  to  assist 
in  the  organization  of  exports,  preparation  of  trade  agreements,  and 
<;ontrol  of  the  quality  of.  goods  exported. 

Executive  orders  published  in  August  1938  incorporajted  into  the 
national  reserves  all  potassium  salts  and  phosphate  rock  (deposits  not 
theretofore  covered  by  concessions,  including  deposits  lying  under 
surfaces  of  privately  owned  property. 

Norway. — A  committee  has  been  organized  for  the  purpose  ot  in- 
vestigation and  study  of  the  various  unfair  trade  practices,  with  a 
view  toward  revision  of  the  Unfair  Competition  Act  of  1922. 

Poland. — The  Law  for  the  Encouragement  of  Private  Investments, 
April  9,  1938,  and  regulations  thereunder,  granted  special  tax  exemp- 
tions on  investments,  for  a  5-year  period,  to  build  up  industries  deemed 
of  national  importance,  including  industrial  plants,  agricultural  proj- 
ects, mineral  and  petroleum  prospecting  and  refineries,  and  building 
plans.  A  law  dated  August  5,  1938,  empowered  the  Minister  of  Agri- 
ture  and  Agrarian  Reform  to  secure  the  supply  of  articles  of  prime 
necessity  (food,  clothing,  and  fuel),  to  store  such  products,  and  to  fix 
prices,  in  order  to  prevent  undue  increase  in  price. 

Peru. — A  law  dated  July  27,  1938,  provided  for  Government  con- 
trol of  the  prices  of  articles  or  services  to  the  public  and  prohibited 
an  increase  in  prices  at  that  time  prevailing  witliout  permission  of 
the  Minister  of  Public  Welfare. 


296  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEH 

Portugal. — Under  decrees  in  1938,  a  board  was  established  to  con- 
trol standards  and  exportation  of  cotton  from  the  colonies,  and  a 
minimum  price  was  fixed.  If  the  landed  cost  of  American  cotton  in 
Portugal  is  lower  than  the  fixed  price  for  the  colonial  product,  the 
difference  is  to  be  refunded  to  the  purchaser  of  colonial  cotton  by  the 
Cotton  Board.  To  provide  funds  for  the  payment  of  this  subsidy,  a 
tax  is  collected  on  all  foreign  cotton  imported. 

Salvador. — A  new  constitution  was  signed  on  January  20, 1939. 

Switzerland. — A  federal  decree  dated  July  8,  1938,  placed  all  war 
materials  under  Government  regulation,  including  arms,  ammunition, 
explosives,  aviation  equipment,  and  chemical  products. 

TurkeU. — The  Tobacco  Monopoly  Act  of  June  10,  1938,  created  a 
State  monopoly  for  control  of  the  culture,  manufacture,  transporta- 
tion, and  sale  of  tobacco  products. 

Venezuela. — A  petroleum  law  published  January  6j  1939,  declared 
the  petroleum  industry  to  be  a  public  utility.  The  right  to  explore, 
exploit,  manufacture,  refine,  and  transport  petroleum  products,  may 
be  exercised  by  the  Government  or  through  concessions  granted  for 
that  purpose.  The  National '  Coffee  Institute  was  reorganized  and 
granted  new  powers,  under  an  executive  decree  of  January  18,  1939. 

Yugoslavia. — A  Government  regulation  issued  June  24,  1938,  pro- 
vided for  formation  of  a  joint  stock  company,  under  Government  own- 
ership and  direction,  which  shall  acquiqre  and  operate  steel  mills,  iron 
foundries,  and  iron  and  coal  mines. 

On  April  1,  1938,  the  Minister  of  Agriculture  was  authorized  to 
draft  plans  for  a  system  of  public  warehouses  for  farm  products.  A 
privileged  company  for  warehouses  wa^  registered  on  August  15,  and 
a  special  board  set  up  for  the  purpose  of  fixing  standards  for  farm 
products  to  be  warehoused.  Government  loans  will  be  granted  on 
products  placed  in  storage.  A  decree  effective  on  July  1, 1938,  author- 
ized a  permanent  fund  for  land  conservation  projects,  flood  control, 
and  soil  improvement.  A  decree  published  on  July  12,  1938,  included 
regulations  for  control  of  fruit  intended  for  exportation. 

A  petroleum  decree  publisx-ied  July  1,  1938,  declared  mineral  oils, 
resins,  and  gases  found  in  the  earth  or  on  its  surface  to  the  property 
of  the  state.  Prospecting  and  exploitation  may  be  conducted  by  the 
Autonomous  State  Monopolies  Administration,  or  concessions  may  be 
granted  under  regulatory  conditions.  Expropriation  by  the  state  is 
permitted.  Imports  and  exports  are  under  Government  control,  and 
maximum  wholesale  prices  may  be  fixed  by  the  Minister  of  Finance. 


EXHIBIT  11 

SELECTED    LIST    OF    REFERENCES    ON    THE    EXPORT 

TRADE  ACT ' 

Anderson,  B.  M.,  Jr.  Competition  and  combination.  The  Webb  Act.  American 
Academy  of  Political  and  Social  Science.    Annals,  March  1919.    V.  82:210-212. 

Barnes,  Joseph.  The  Webb-Pomerene  Act  of  1918.  In  Government  promotion 
of  foreign  trade  in  the  United  States.  Prepared  for  the  fifth  Biennial  Con- 
ference of  the  Institution  of  Pacific  Relations.  .  .  .  Banff,  Canada,  August  14 
to  28,  1933.    New  York,  American  Council  institute  of  Pacific  Relations,  1933. 

Bartells,  E.  J.  The  Webb  law  in  operation.  Address  before  the  Seventh  National 
Foreign  Trade  Convention,  May  14,  1920,  at  San  Francisco,  New  York,  Na- 
tional Foreign  Trade  Council,  1920.    pp.  658-663. 

Beer,  Henry  Ward.  America's  answer  to  foreign  combines.  American  exporters 
meet  the  cartel  menace  on  its  own  ground.  Export  Trade  and  Finance,  July  7, 
1928.     V.  19 :  15-18. 

Bissell,  L.  H.  The  Webb  Act :  its  legal  aspects.  An  address  delivered  at  the 
Sixth  National  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  Chicago,  April  25,  1919.  New  York, 
National  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1919.     pp.  461-470. 

Brown,  James  L.  Exporting  through  the  Webb-Law  Associations.  Comparative 
Law  Series,  June  1939.    V.  2:  (new  series)  257-275. 

Charls,  George  H.  Organization  of  a  district  export  selling  company  under  the 
Webb  law.  An  address  delivered  at  the  Fifth  National  Foreign  Trade  Con- 
vention, Cincinnati,  April  18,  1918.  New  York,  National  Foreign  Trade  Council, 
1918.    pp.    318-344. 

Colt,  Frederick  A.  Exporting  cotton  textiles.  Address  delivered  at  the  Twentieth 
National  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  Pittsburgh,  April  26,  1933.  New  York, 
National  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1933.    pp.  163-169. 

Colt,  Frederick  A.  The  operation  of  Webb-law  export  associations — Textiles. 
Address  delivered  at  the  Eighteenth  National  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  New 
York,  May  28,  1931.  New  York,  National  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1931.  pp. 
233-240. 

Colver,  William  B.  Concentration  and  control  ii'  industry  and  trade.  In 
American  problems  of  reconstruction,  Elisha  M.  Friedman,  ed.  New  York, 
-E.  P.  Button  &  Co.,  1918.    pp.  177-195. 

Copland,  D.  B.  and  Norris,  J.  G.  Some  reciprocal  effects  of  our  Anti-trust  laws 
with  special  reference  to  Australia.  (With  particular  reference  to  the  Webb- 
Pomerene  Act)  American  Academy  of  Political  and  Social  Science.  Annals, 
January  1930.     V.  147 :  117-124. 

Davies,  Joseph  E.  Combinations  for  export  trade  under  the  Webb  Act.  Amer- 
ican Academy  of  Political  and  Social  Science.  Annals,  March  1919.  V.  82: 
150-158. 

Davies,  Joseph  E.  Cooperation  in  foreign  trade.  Address  delivered  at  the 
Third  National  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  New  Orleans,  January  28,  1916. 
New  York,  National  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1916.    pp.  454-462. 

De  Courcy,  Harold,  and  Brown,  James  L.  The  export  trade  act,  by  H.  De 
Courcy,  and  export  trade  through  Webb-law  associations,  by  James  L.  Brown. 
Washington,  D.  C,  U.  S.  Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce,  1935. 
G.  L.  B.  162.    35  pp.    Processed. 

De  Courcy,  Harold.  Increased  exports  of  Webb  Act  associations.  Commerce 
Reports'  October  28, 1937.    p.  838. 


» Compiled  by  Madge  E.  Harkness,  assistant  librarian,  Federal  Trade  Commission. 

297 


298  CONCENTKATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Donovan,  J.  J.  The  operation  of  Webb  law  export  associations — Douglas  Fir. 
Address  delivered  at  the  Eighteenth  National  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  New 
York,  May  28,  1931.  New  York,  National  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1931.  pp. 
240-250. 

Duncan,  C.  S.  Legalizing  combinations  for  export  trade.  Journal  of  Political 
Economy,  April  1917.    V.  25  :  313-338. 

Fort,  John  Franklin.  Webb  law  and  foreign  trade.  Scribner's  Magazine,  May 
1919.    V.  65 :  &4a-644. 

Fournier,  Leslie.  The  purposes  and  results  of  the  Webb-Pomerene  Law.  Amer- 
ican Economic  Review,  March  1932.    V.  22:18-33. 

Gent,  Ernest  V.  After  the  W.  R.  A. — The  Webb-Pomerene  Act.  An  address  de- 
livered at  the  Twentj'-second  National  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  Houston, 
November  19,  1935.  New  York,  National  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1935.  pp. 
18-20. 

Gent,  Ernest  V.  America  fights  for  foreign  markets.  World's  Work,  May  1030. 
V.  59 :  24-27,  115. 

<3ent,  Ernest  V.  Operation  of  Webb  Law  export  associations — Zinc.  An  address 
at  the  Eigliteenth  National  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  New  York,  May  28, 
1931.    New  York,  National  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1931.    pp.  220-227. 

Gent,  Ernest  V.  Why  is  not  the  Webb  law  used  more  generally  by'inland  manu- 
facturers engaged  in  foreign  trade?  An  address  before  the  Twentieth  National 
Foreign  Trade  Convention,  April  27,  1933,  at  Pittsburgh,  Pa.  New  York,  Na- 
tional Foreign  Trade  Council,  1933-.    pp.  335-346. 

Grace,  Morgan  H.  Twelve  years'  experience  with  Webb  law  associations.  An 
address  before  the  Eighteenth  National  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  New  York, 
May  28,  1931.    New  York,  National  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1931.    pp.  245-250. 

Guaranty  Trust  Co.  of  New  York.  Combining  for  foreign  trade,  plans  and 
methods  of  oijeration.     New  York,  Guaranty  Trust  Co.,  1920.     15  pp. 

Guaranty  Trust  Co.  of  New  York.  Export  trade  combinations  permitted  by  the 
Webb  law.    New  York,  Guaranty  Trust  Co.,  1918.    46  pp. 

Guest,  Charles  E.  The  operation  of  Y'  bb  law  export  associations — Rubber.  An 
address  delivered  at  the  Eighteenth  .  Uional  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  New 
York,  May  28,  1931.  New  York,  Nat-  Hal  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1931.  pp. 
227-233. 

Hines,  Walker  D.  Cotton  Textile  Institute  takes  steps  to  strengthen  export 
trade.  Joint  representation  under  the  Webb-Pomerene  Act.  Textile  World, 
January  19,  1929.     V.  75:353-354. 

Huebncr.  Grover  G.,  and  Kramer,  Roland  L.  Cooperative  exporting  in  the 
United  States.  In  Foreign  trade — principles  and  practice.  New  York,  Apple- 
ton  &  Co.  1931.     Chapter  XXII. 

Burley,  Edward  N.  Awakening  of  business.  New  York,  Doubleday,  Page  & 
Co.,  1919.     Chapters  VII-XII. 

Hurley,  Edward  N.  Co-operation  in  foreign  trade.  An  address  before  the 
Seventeenth  National  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  May  22,  1930,  at  Los  Angeles. 
New  York,  National  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1930.    pp.  172-176. 

Interpretation  by  Federal  Trade  Commission  of  provisions  of  Webb-Pomerene 
Export  Trade  Act  respecting  formation  of  export  association  by  silver  producers. 
Commercial  and  Financial  Chronicle,  August  9,  1924.     V.  119:  649-650. 

Jones,  Eliot.  The  Webb-Pomerene  Act.  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  No- 
vember 1920.    V.  28 :  754-767. 

Jones,  Franklin  D.  Export  as.sociations.  In  Trade  association  activities  and 
the  law.    New  York,  McGraw-Hill,  1922.    pp.  223-236. 

Judd,  Edwin  E.  Export  Management  under  the  Webb-Pomerene  Act.  An  ad- 
dress before  the  Seventh  National  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  May  14,  1020, 
at  San  Francisco.  New  York,  National  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1920.  Pp. 
664-670. 

Judd,  Edwin  E.  Webb-Pomerene  Act  problems.  Experience  and  difficulties  of  the 
export  manager  of  one  corporation  organized  under  this  act.  World  Markets, 
June  1920.     V.  7:  47-48. 

TCir.sh,  Benjamin  S.  Foreign  trade  functions  of  trade  associations.  ITniverstty 
of  Pennsylvania  Law  Review,  June  1928.     V.  76:  891-925. 

Klrsh.  Benjamin  S.  Trade  Associations  in  law  and  business.  New  York, 
Central  Book  Company,  1938.  Chapter  XI,  Foreign  Trade  Functions,  pp. 
321-374. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  299 

Klein,  Julius.  Foreign  trade  combinations.  An  address  before  Foreign  Com- 
merce Group  luncheon,  May  8,  1928.  Sixteenth  annual  meeting  Chamber  of 
Commerce  of  the  United  States  of  America.    U.  S.  Daily,  May  9,  1928.    pp.  1,  5. 

Kramer,  Roland  L.  The  American  cartel  system  in  export  trade.  Success 
and  failure  experienced  by  Export  associations  organized  under  the  Webb- 
Pomerene  Act.     Export  Trade  and  Finance,  October  27,  1928.     V.  19:  7-9. 

Lamb,  George  N.  Selling  American  walnut  abroad — Seven  years'  actual  ex- 
perience of  a  combination  under  the  Webb-Pomerene  Act.  Export  Tl-ade  and 
Finance,  October  23,  1926.    V.  16:  11-15. 

Litman,  Simon.  Combinations  for  export  trade.  In  Essentials  of  International 
trade.    New  York,  John  Wiley  and  Sons,  Inc.,  1927.    2d  ed.    Chapter  XXIV. 

Love,  Ellen  L.  The  Export  Trade  Act  (Webb-Pomerene  law).  George  Wash- 
of  Pennsylvania  Law^  Review,  June  1928.    V.  76  :  891-925. 

Montague,  Gilbert  H.  Agreements  in  American  export  trade.  An  address  at  the 
Fourteenth  National  Foreign  Trade  Con'^'ention.  May  27,  1927,  at  Detroit,  Mich. 
New  York,  National  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1927.    pp.  400-414. 

Montague,  Gilbert  H.  Cooperation  in  foreign  trade:  why  not  at  home?  An 
address  delivered  at  the  luncheon  session  of  the  American  Manufacturers 
Export  Association  and  the  National  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  New  Yorl^, 
May  28,  1931.     New  York,  National  Foreign  Trade  Council,  1931.     pp.  215-219: 

Montague,  Gilbert  H.  Cooperation  under  the  Webb-Pomerene  law  for  the  re- 
habilitation of  Europe  after  the  war.  An  address  delivered  at  the  Fifth  National 
Foreign  Trade  Convention,  Cincinnati,  April  18.  1918.  New  York,  National 
Foreign  Trade  Council,  1918.    pp.  302-317. 

Montague,  Gilbert  H.  The  Federal  Trade  Commission's  investigation  of  foreign 
trade  conditions  (Report  on  Cooperation  in  Export  Trade).  American  Academy 
of  Political  and  Social  Science.    Annals,  January  1916.    V.  63:67-68. 

Montague,  Gilbert  H.  The  Webb  bill  and  the  antitrust  laws.  American  Bar 
Association  Journal,  April  1917.    Vol.  3  :  145-161. 

National  Association  of  Manufacturers  of  the  United  States  of  America.  Export 
trade  development.  A  plan  for  the  organization  and  conduct  of  export  corpora- 
tions .  .  .  under  the  Webb-Pomerene  Act.  New  York.  The  Association,  1919. 
10  pp. 

National  Association  of  Manufacturers  of  the  United  States  of  America.  The 
Namusa  plan  for  export  trade  development.  A  nonprofit  organization  in- 
corporated in  the  State  of  New  York  and  qualified  as  an  export  association 
under  the  Webb-Pomerene  Act.     New  York,   The  Association,   1919.     12  pp. 

National  Foreign  Trade  Council.  The  Webb  bill.  Report  of  Committee  on 
Cooperation  in  Foreign  Trade.  .  .  .  for  enactment  of  H.  R.  17350  (Webb  bill)  ; 
Fourth  National  Foreign  Trade  Convention,  Pittsburgh,  January  25.  1917. 
New  York,  The  Council,  1917.    pp.  155-182. 

National  Shawmut  Bank  of  Boston.  An  introduction  to  the  Webb  law.  An 
act  to  promote  export  trade  and  for  other  purposes.  Approved  April  10-, 
1918.    Boston.  1910,  32  pp.     (Shawmut  Series  No.  109.) 

Notz,  William  F.,  and  Harvey,  Richard  S.  American  foreign  trade,  as  promoted 
by  the  Webh-Pomorene  and  Edge  Acts  with  historical  references  to  the  origin 
and  enforcement  of  the  antitrust  laws.  Indianapolis,  Bobbs-Merrill  Co., 
1921.     593  pp. 

Notz,  William  F.  Export  trade  problems  and  an  American  foreign  trade  policy. 
Journal  of  Political  Economy,  February  1918.     V.  26:  105-124. 

Nolz.  William  F.  New  phases  of  unfair  competition  and  measures  for  its  sup- 
pression— national  and  international.  Yale  Law  Journal,  February  1921. 
V.  30:384-394. 

Notz,  William  F.  Ten  years'  operation  of  the  Webb  law.  American  Economic 
Reviev.  March  1929.  'v.  19:9-19 

Notz  William  F.  The  Webb  laAv,  its  scope  and  operation.  Journal  of  Political 
Economy.  July  1919.     V.  27  :  .525-543. 

Notz,  William  F.  The  Webb-Pomerene  Act — its  importance  to  the  foreign  credit 
man.     Credit  Monthly.  .Lnnuary  1922.     V.  24 :  9-16. 

Notz,  William  F.  The  Webb-Pomerene  law — extraterritorial  scope  of  the  nn- 
falr   competition   clause.      Yale   Law   Journal,   November   1919.      V.    29:29-45. 

Putting  tosrether  the  tvplcal  export  associations.  The  Americas.  February  1919. 
V.  5 :  8-il. 

Regulation   of  export  practices  by   the   Federal  Trade  Board.     The  Ame 
November  1918.     V.  5  :  13-15. 


300  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Savay,  Norbert.  The  Webb-Pomerene  law.  In  Principles  of  Foreign  Trade. 
New  York,  Ronald  Press  Company,  1919.    Chapters  17-19. 

Snider,  Guy  Edward,  comp.  Selling  in  foreign  marlcets.  Miscellaneous  Series 
No.  81,  Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce.  Washington,  D.  C,  Gov- 
ernment Printing  Office,  1919.     Chapter  VIII.     Export  Combinations. 

Thompson,  Huston.  A  Federal  Trade  Commission  appraisal  of  Webb-Pomerene 
law.  It  has  promoted  business  economies  and  greater  efficiency  in  the  handling 
of  our  export  trade.  Export  Trade  and  Exporters  Review,  October  1,  1921. 
V.  6 :  29-34. 

Thompson,  Huston.  How  the  Export  Trade  Act  (Webb-Pomerene  Law)  is  oper- 
ating. American  Business  &  National  Acceptance  Journal,  September  W21. 
V.  4:12-13. 

Thompson,  Huston.  Our  foreign  trade  problem :  results  of  Federal  supervision 
and  control.    Forum,  July  1920.    V.  64 :  70-78. 

U.  S.  Congress.  House.  Committee  on  the  Judiciary.  To  promote  export  trade, 
and  for  other  purposes.  Hearings,  64th  Cong.,  1st  sess.  on  H.  R.  16707.  July  IS, 
20,  1916.    Government  Printing  Office,  1916.    82  pp. 

U.  S.  Congress.  House.  Committee  on  the  Judiciary.  Promotion  of  export 
trade,  etc.  Report.  To  accompany  H.  R.  17350.  Government  Printing  Office, 
1916.  4  pp.  Ordered  printed  August  15,  1916.  House  report  1118,  64th  Cong., 
1st  sess. 

U.  S.  Congress.  Senate.  Committee  on  Interstate  Commerce.  Promotion  ot' 
export  trade.  Hearings,  64th  Cong.,  2d  sess.  on  H.  R.  17350.  January  5,  1917. 
Government  Printing  Office,  1917.    156  pp. 

U.  S.  Congress.  Senate.  Committee  on  Interstate  Commerce.  Export  trade. 
Report.  To  accompany  H.  R.  17350.  Government  Printing  Office,  1917.  4  pp. 
Ordered  printed  February  14,  1917.     Senate  report  1056,  64th  Cong.,  2d  sess. 

U.  S.  Congress.  Senate.  Committee  on  Interstate  Commerce.  Export  trade. 
Report.  To  accompany  S.  634.  Government  Printing  Office,  1917.  4  pp. 
Ordered  printed  April  16,  1917.    Senate  report  9,  65th  Cong.,  1st  sess. 

U.  S.  Congress.  House.  Committee  on  the  Judiciary.  Promotion  of  export 
trade.  Report.  To  accompany  H.  R.  2316.  Government  Printing  Office,  1917. 
10  pp.     Ordered  printed  May  11,  1917.     House  report  50,  65th  Cong.,  1st  ses.s. 

T^.  S.  Congress.  Senate.  Committee  on  Interstate  Commerce.  Export  trade. 
Report.  To  accompany  H.  R.  2316.  Government  Printing  Office,  1917.  4  pp. 
Ordered  printed  August  20,  1917.     Senate  report  109,  65th  Cong.,  1st  sess. 

U.  S.  Congress.  Conference  Committees,  1918.  Promotion  of  export  trade.  Con- 
ference report.  To  accompany  H.  R.  2316.  Government  Printing  Office,  1918. 
3  pp      Ordered  printed  April  5,  1918.     House  report  468,  65th  Cong.,  2d  sess. 

U.  S.  Federal  Trade  Commission.  Annual  reports.  Washington,  Government 
Printing  Office,  1915-39. 

U.  S.  Federal  Trade  Commission.  Discussion  of  practice  and  procedure  under 
the  Export  Trade  Act  (Webb-Pomerene  law).  Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  1,  1919. 
13  pp.  Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  2,  1935.  23  pp.  Government  Printing  Office, 
1919,  1935. 

U.  S.  Federal  Trade  Commission.  Report  on  Cooperation  in  American  Export 
Trade.  Washington,  Government  Printing  Office,  1916.  2  pts.  (This  report  was 
the  result  of  a  comprehensive  study  and  recommended  the  passage  of  the 
Export  Trade  Act.) 

tJ.  S.  Laws,  statutes,  etc.  Webb-Pomerene  Act.  An  act  to  promote  export  trade, 
and  for  other  purposes.  Approved  April  10,  1918.  Government  Printing  Office, 
1918.  3  pp.  Public,  No.  126,  65th  Cong.  (H.  R.  2316),  40  Stat.  516,  15  U.  S.  C.  A. 
sec.  61. 

Wallace,  Benjamin  B.,  and  Edminster,  Lynn  R.  A  third  possible  exception  to 
our  historic  policy  of  nonrestriction  of  exports  grows  out  of  tlie  federal  law 
permitting  combinations  for  export  trading  (Webb-Pomerene  Act).  In  Inter- 
national Control  of  Raw  Materials.  Washington,  D.  C.,  Brookings  Institution, 
1930.    pp.  258-265. 

Walsh,  John.  The  Webb  law  in  operation.  Address  before  the  Sixth  National 
Foreign  Trade  Convention,  Chicago,  April  25,  1919.  New  York,  National  For- 
eign Trade  Council,  1919.    pp.  449-461. 

The  Webb-Pomerene  Law.     The  Americas,  February  1919.    V.  5 :  3-8. 


i 


INDEX 


Page 

AGRICULTURE:  Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States,  1937 101-103 

ALGERIA:   Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,   1938;  sum- 
mary        290 

ANTIMONY:  Only  smelter  in  United  States  owned  abroad 106 

ARGENTINA : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1036 264 

1937-38 . 275 

1938' 290 

ARTIFICIAL  TEETH  MANUFACTURE :  Pricing  policv,  export  market—         47 
ASSOCIATIONS:  EXPORT  TRADE  ACT.      {See  Export  Trade  Associa- 
tions.) 
AUSTRALIA: 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1936-37 264 

1938 290 

AUSTRIA  : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation  :  summary  : 

1936 264 

IQ^g 291 

AUTOMOTIVE    CHEMICALS:    Pricing   policies,    export   market I— I        56 

AUTOMOTIVE  INDUSTRY : 

Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States,  1937 ;  automobile  parts ; 

dollar  amount 100 

Pi-icing  policies  :  Domestic  and  export  market 42 

BALANCE  OF  INTERNATIONAL  PAYMENTS.     (See  Investments.) 
BANKING,    INVESTMENTS,    etc. :    Foreign    capital    invested    in    United 

States.  1937:  dollar  amount 101 

BELGIUM:    Trust    laws    and    unfair    competition    legislation,    1938-39; 

summarv 291 

BIOLOGICAL    PRODUCTS:     Pricing    policies:     Domestic    and    export 

market , 56 

BOLIVIA : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation;  summary: 

1936 . 264 

1938 276,  291 

BORON  MINERALS  INDUSTRY:  Percent  of  domestic  output  by  com- 
panies under  foreign  control 106 

BRAZIL:    Trust    laws    and    unfair    competition    legislation.     1938    sum- 
marv        291 

BUILDING    MATERIALS    INDUSTRY:    Foreign    capital    invested    in 

United  States.  1937 100 

CACAO  CARTEL:  International  agreement  for  a  buyers'  pool,  1937 280 

CALCULATING  MACHINES:  Pricing  policies,  export  market 41 

CALLMAN,  DR.  RUDOLPH:  Das  deutsche  Kartellrecht ;  cited  (n.) x 

CANADA : 

Trust  laws"and  unfair-competition  legislation;  summary: 

1937 "^65 

1938 -^6 

193&-39 292 

301 


302  INDEX 

Cartels  (see  also  heloio  References  to  Literature,  items  1,  4,  12)  :  Page 

Branches  of  foreign  cartels  or  subsidiaries  in  United  States 99 

Federal  Trade  Commission's  report  of  1916  summarizing  status  of 

foreign  cartels 115 

Germany,  pre-war  cartels 115 

International  agreements  and  cartels,  entered  into  or  revised : 

1937 268 

1937-38 280 

CEMENT  INTERNATIONAL  AGREEMENT,  1937 268 

CHAMBERLAIN,  E. :  Theory  of  monopolistic  competition  ;  cited  (n.) 78 

CHEMICAL  INDUSTRY : 

Export  price  policy  of  principal  world  supplier  of  a  chemical  product 32 

Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States,  1937 ;  comment  and  dollar 

amount 100-101 

German  pre-war  investment  in  United  States 101 

Pricing  policies,  export  market  of  heavy  chemicals  industry 46 

CHINA  :  Trust  laws  and  unfair-competition  legislation  of  1936 ;  summary 265 

CIGARETTE  MANUFACTURE  :  Pricing  policies,  export  market 46 

COFFEE  INTERNATIONAL  CONFERENCE,  1936 268 

COKE,  INTERNATIONAL  CARTEL,  1937 279-280 

COLOMBIA : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair-competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1936 265 

293g 293. 

COMMISSION  houses":  Export  price  policy II II         61 

COMPETITION  {See  also  below  References  to  Literature,  items  2,  17)  : 

Competition    versus    monopoly 74-80 

Unfair   competition   legislation   in    foreign   countries,   1937-39;    sum- 
mary : 

1937 264 

1938 275 

1939 290 

COMPRESSORS  (See  Machinery  Products.) 

CONSTRUCTION  INDUSTRY.      (See  Building  Materials  Industry.) 

COPPER   CARTEL 116 

COPPER  EXPORT  ASSOCIATION:  Function  of x 

COPPER  EXPORTERS,  INC.:  Function  of y 

COST  OF  DOING  BUSINESS  :  Export  Trade.     (See  Export  Trade  :  Costs.) 

COTTON  PIECE  GOODS  INDUSTRY:  Export  pricing  policy 38 

COTTON  STAPLES  INDUSTRY:  Pricing  policy,  export  market 62 

CUBA :  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation  of  1938 ;  summary^       276 
CZECHOSLOVAKIA : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1936 265 

1937 276 

1938 293 

DENMARK:  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,  1937;  sum- 
mary        277 

DICKENS,  PAUL  D. 

American  direct  investments  in  forei.i^n  countries,  1936;  cited   (n.)__       109 
Direct  foreign  investments  in  American  industry,  193";  1940;  cited 

and    text x,  85-110 

DOMINICAN  REPUBLIC :  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation 

1938  ;    sum"mary 293 

DUMPING    iSec  also   hclotv  References  to  Literature,  item  28)  : 

Federal    Trade    Commission,    supplemental    report    on    antidumping 

legislation,  1934-38;  cited 275,290 

Theory  of 4  83 

ECUADOR : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1937-38 . 277 

1938 293 

EGYPT  :  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,  1938 ;  summary___      293 
ESTONIA  :  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,  1937 ;  summary__       277 


INDEX  303 

EXPORT  PRICE   POLICIES    (See  also  hclow  References  to  Literature,     Page 
items  11,  14.  19.  23,  26)  : 

Comparison  of  export-  and  domestic-price  policies 29-62 

Domestic-  and  export-sales  departments  establish  prices  independently 
on  basis  of  factory  costs  plus  distribution  costs;  some  concessions 

in  exports 52 

Early  studies  of 7_H 

Economic  factors  determining  export-price  policy 63-90 

Export  agents  and  commission  houses  acting  for  American  manufac- 
turers           61 

Export  customer  different  type  than  domestic 47 

Export  prices  equal  to  domestic  prices 36,68 

Export  prices  higher  than  domestic 25,  63,  67 

Lower  export  than  domestic  prices 44,70 

Foreign  sales  made  by  company  branches ;  price  concessions  in  some 

markets . 58 

Factors  in  foreign  market  conditions  which  necessitate  lower  export 

prices 72 

Factory  price  wlus  distribution  costs  for  all  customers 37 

Foreign  branch  plants,  effect  of 90 

Foreign  sales  made  at  less  than  average  costs 50 

International  price  discrimination  not  a  sign  of  monopoly 91 

Market  price  plus  distribution  costs  for  all  customers 36 

Mass  production  and 83-86 

Monopoly  aspects  of  tlie  problem "     74 

Monopoly  prices . 31 

One-price  policy  for  all  customers 39 

Problems  involved  in  comparing  domestic  and  export  prices 16-29 

Profit   margin    differentials 28 

Public  control  of  export  prices 92 

Range  in  export  versus  domestic  prices  for  identical  product ;  table 57 

Sample  study  of  differences  between  domestic  and  export  pricing  policy 

of  United  States  corporations.    By  Dr.  Milton  Gilbert 1-93 

Standard  export  prices  lower  than  domestic  for  some  commodities 50 

Standard  export  prices  same  as  domestic  but  concessions  given  in  some 

markets • 44 

Why  a  firm  is  willing  to  grant  price  concessions  on  export  shipments 70 

Why  domestic  prices  are  higher 74 

Zone  price  system 40 

EXPORT  TRADE:  BALANCE  OF  PAYMENTS.     {See  Investments.) 
EXPORT  TRADE; COSTS: 

Group  1  cases  analysis ;  higher  export  tlian  domestic  prices.^ 31-36 

Group  2  cases  analysis ;  export  prices  equal  to  domestic  prices 36-^4 

Group  3  cases  aiialvsis;  lower  export  than  domestic  prices 44-62 

EXPORT  TRADE  ;  PROFITABILITY  : 

Group  1  cases  analysis ;  higher  export  than  domestic  prices 31-36 

Group  2  cases  analysis:  export  prices  equal   to  domestic  prices 36-44 

Group  3  cases  analysis;  lower  export  than  domestic  prices 44-62 

Type  of  price  policy  analysis : 

All  foreign   sales  made  at   less  than  average  costs:   six   named 

products:  comment  and  tabh^ 59-61 

All  foreign  sales  made  by  company  branches ;  concessions  in  some 

markets;  calculation  of  profits 58-59 

Domestic  and  export  sales  dejiartments  establish  prices  inde- 
pendently on  basis  of  factory  plus  distril)ntion  costs;  some 
concessions    in    exports:    15    nam"d    products;    comment    and 

table 52-58 

Standard  export  prices  lower  than  domestic  for  some  commodi- 
ties; six  named  products,  comment  and  table 50-52 

Standard  export  prices  same  as  domestic  but  concessions  given 

in  some  markets;  15  named  products,  comment  and  tables 44-50 

EXPORT  TRADE  :  REFERENCES  TO  LITERATURE.     (See  bcloiv  Refer- 
ences to  Literature,  items  5-10,  27.) 


304  INDEX 

EXPORT  TRADE  ACT    (April  10,  1918,  40  Stat.  516.    Webb-Pomerene     Pag«- 
Act)  : 

Administration  of  the  law 123- 

Advantages  derived  by  cooperative  effort  under  act 143 

Amendmeiit  proposed  in  1921,  by  Senator  Fletcher,   S.  2683,   Sixty- 
seventh  Congress ;  text  of  bill 124 

Analysis  of  law  as  passed  on  April  10,  1918 119 

Annual  report  form  of  associations  under  act 237 

Associated  group-^  formed  under  the  act,  1918-38 ;  summary  in  chrono- 
logical   order 132 

Bills,    debates,    and   hearings,    and    reports,    1924-28,    redrafting   or 

amending  provisions  of  Export  Trade  Act ;  summary 128 

Debates  in  Congress,  hearings  and  committee  reports  preceding  pas- 
sags  of  the  act 118-119 

Federal  Trade  Commission  statements  of  Export  Trade  Act  activi- 
ties, 1916-39;  summary 131 

Future  of  the  law 146 

Operation  of,   report  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission ;   cited  and 

text X,  111-300 

Practice  and  procedure  under  the  act.     Federal  Trade  Commission, 

Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  1,  1919;  extracts;  text 123,240 

Practice  and  procedure  under  the  act.     Federal  Trade  Commission : 

Foreign  Trade  Series,  No.  2,  1985 ;  cited  and  text 129,  251 

Procedure  of  Federal  Trade  Commission  under  act ;  summary 132 

Section  5.  Pacific  Forest  Industries  case;  action  by  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission, 1939'-40;  text  of  recommendations,  January  27,  1940 12&-130- 

Selected  list  of  references  on  the  Export  Trade  Act,  compiled  by  Madge 

E.  Harkness 297-300 

Silver  letter,  1924;  text 125 

Text  of  the  law  as  approved  April  10,  1918 149-151 

Text  of  the  law  as  approved  April  10,  1918;  annotated 245-249 

Wilson  Tariff  Act  antitrust  amendments  not  modified  by  act 249 

EXPORT  TRADE  ASSOCIATIONS  : 

Advantages  obtained  by  the  associations 288 

Annual   report,   form   of : 287 

Directory  of  associations  on  file  with  Federal  Trade  Commission : 

June  30,  1937  (45) 261 

June  30,  1938   (44) 274 

June  30,  1939  (43) 286 

Feb.  1940  (44) 152-253 

Directory  of  associations  that  have  operated  or  been  formed  imder  the 
act: 

1918-35 258-260 

1918-39 154-233. 

Functions  of  the  groups  organized  under  the  act 138 

Number  of  associations  in  operatioia  each  year,  1920-40;  number  of 

member  companies  represented  in  1940;  table 135 

Obstacles  met  by  export  associations ;  reasons  for  dissolution  of  some 

of  the  groups 145. 

Report  to  Federal  Trade  Commission  due  within  30  days  after  cre- 
ation of  each  association;  facsimile  in  blank 234 

Services  rendered  by  the  associations 287 

Types  of  organization  formed  under  act 136 

Value  of  products  exported  : 

1920^34 257 

1920-38 134 

1925-38 284-285 

1935-36 262 

FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION: 

Alleged   violation   of   antitrust    laws    by   combinations    being   formed 
abroad  by  American  firms  and  alleged  dumping  of  American  goods 

in  foreign  markets;  report  1926;  cited   (n.) 10,16 

Annual  report,  excerpts  relating  to  foreign  trade  work  of  the  Com- 
mission : 

1937 261-263 

1938 272 

1939 284 


INDEX  305 

FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION— Continued  Page 

Cooperation  in  American  export  trade;  report  1916;  extracts 113 

Export  Trade  Act  activities,  statements  by  Commission  ;  summary 131 

Export  trade  associations  on  file  with  the  Commission : 

June  30,   1937    (45) 262-263 

June  30,   1938    (44) 274 

June  30,  1938  (43)—, 286 

Feb.  1940  (44) 15^153 

Export  Trade  Division : 

Creation   of - 123 

Name  changed  to  Export  Trade  Section,  July  1,  1927 129 

Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  1.     Discussion  of  practice  and  procedure 

under  the  Export  Trade  Act,  1919,  extracts;  text 123,240 

Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  2.     Practice  and  procedure  under  the  Expoi  t 

Trade  Act,  1935;  cited  and  text 129,251 

Pacific  Forest  Industries,  an  export  association ;  recommendations  for 

readjustment  of  business  of,  January  27,  1940;  text 129-130 

Pacific  Forest  Industries,  effect  of  recommendations  of  January  27, 

1940 138 

Procedi '  e  under  Export  Trade  Act ;  summary 132 

Report  on  the  operation  of  the  Export  Trade  Act   ( Webb-Pomerene 

law),  1918-40;  cited  and  text x,  111-300 

"Silver  letter,"  July  31,  1924,  to  Silver  Producers'  Committee  ;  text 125 

FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION  ACT  ( SEPTEMBER  26,  1914.     28  Stat. 
717)  : 

Section  6  (h),  inquiry  on  trade  conditions  in  and  with  foreign  coun- 
tries: text 113,  250 

FERTILIZER  INDUSTRY.      (See  Boron  Minerals  Industry;   Phosphate 

Industry;  Potash  Industry). 
FINANCIAL  INSTITUTIONS : 

Foreign  capital  in  the  United  States,  1937 ;  comment  and  table 101-102 

Insurance..    (See  Insurance. ) 
FINLAND:  Trust    laws   and    unfair   competition    legislation,    1938,    sum- 

marv 293 

FOODSTUFFS  INDUSTRY:  Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States, 

1937 100 

FOREIGN  CAPITAL  IN  THE  UNITED  STATES.     (See  Investments.) 
FOREIGN  COUNTRIES: 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  in ;  excerpts  from  annual  report 
Federal  Trade  Commission : 

1937 264 

1938 275 

1939 290 

FORMULAE  EMPLOYED  IN   STUDY: 

Basis  of  export  price  quotations,  f.  o.  b.,  f.  a.  s.,  c.  i.  f 22 

Credit  terms  to  domestic  and  export  customers 25 

Draw-backs 22 

Export  price  differentials 20 

Export  price  list  timing - —        21 

Price  quotation  to  similar  types  of  buyers 25 

Special  packing  cost  differentials 24 

FOUNTAIN  PENS.     (See  Stationery  Goods.) 
FRANCE : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation;  summary: 

1936-37 266 

1937-38 277 

1938-39 293 

GERMANY : 

Cartels,    pre-war 115 

Investment  in  United  States  chemical  industry,  pre-war 101 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1936-37 266 

1937-38 278 

1938 294 

GILP>ERT.  DR.  MILTON:  A  sample  study  of  differences  between  domestic 

and  export  pricing  policv  of  the  United  States  corporations ix,  1-93 

GOVERNMENT  CONTROL  OF  EXPORT  PRICES 92 


306  INDEX 

GREAT  BRITAIN :  Page 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1936 267 

1937-38 279 

1938-^9 294 

GREECE '. 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1936 , : 267 

1938 294 

HABERLER,  GOTTFRIED  VON:  Theory  of  international  trade;  cited 

(n.) 6,77 

HARKNESS,   MADGE  E.,   compiler:  Selected   list   of   references   on   the 

Export  Trade  Act 297-300 

HOSIEKY:  WOMEN'S  WEAR:  Pricing  policy,  export  market 40 

HOSIERY  MANUFACTURE  :  Pricing  policies  export  market 42 

HOUSEHOLD  TEXTILE  GOODS  :  Pricing  policies  export  market :  towels, 

bed  linens 60 

INDIA  :  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation  of  1937  ;  summary 268 

INSURANCE.     (See  also  below  References  to  Literature,  item  22)  : 

Foreign  capital  investment  in  United  States,  1937 ;  type  of  insurance ; 

comment  and  table 101-102 

INTERNATIONAL  CARTELS.     (See  Cartels.) 

INTERNATIONAL  PAYMENTS.     (See  Investments.) 

INTERNATIONAL  PRICE  DISCRIMINATION.     Not  a  sign  of  monopoly.         91 

INTERNATIONAL  SUGAR  COUNCIL:  Establishment  of,  1937 268 

INVESTMENTS    (see  also  below  References  to  Literature,  items  3,   13, 
20-22) : 

American  capital  in  foreign  countries,  1936.     By  Paul  D.  Dickens ; 

cited  (n.) 109 

Foreign  capital  in  the  United  States : 

Amounts  of  1937,  long-term,  by  categories  aild  short-term ;  com- 
ment and  table  1 99 

Amount    by    principal    countries    and   industries ;    comment    and 

table  3 103 

Concentration  of  assets  and  investment;  comment  and  table  G--  108-109 

Control  of  United  States  production 105 

Direct  investments  by  countries,  1937;  comment  and  table  4 105 

Direct  investments,   dollar  amount  by  industry,   1937 ;   comment 

and  table  2 100 

Foreign   investments   in   American   industry,    1937.     By   Paul   D. 

Dickens ,__  85-110 

Geographical  distribution;  comment  and  table 104-105 

Industrial  distribution;  comment  and  table 100-103 

International  affiliations  of  American   industry,  1937 ;   comment 

and  table  5 105-108 

IRAN:  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,  1937;  summary 280 

IRON   AND    STEEL   INDUSTRY;    Foreign    capital    invested    in    United 

States,    1937 100 

Scrap-iron,  international  convention  of,  1937 268 

ITALY : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1936 268 

1937_, 280 

1938 295 

JAPAN : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summarv : 

1936 268 

1937-38 280 

1938-^9 295 

KREPS,  THEODORE  J. : 

Explanatory   introductory  statement   to  Monograph   No.   6 ix-xii 

Export,    Import,    domestic    prices    in    the    United    States,    1926-30, 

cited  (n. ) ^ x 

LABORATORY     APPARATUS     INDUSTRY:  Pricing     policies,     export 
market. 


INDEX  307 

LATVIA :  Page 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

193&^7 , 269 

1937--, 281 

1938 ^ 295 

LIEFMANN,  DR.  ROBERT:  Cartels,  combines,  and  trusts,  cited x 

LIQUOR  INDUSTRY :  Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States,  1937_^      lOl 
LITHUANIA:  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,   193&-37; 

summary 269 

MACHINE  TOOL  INDUSTRY :  Pricing  policies,  export  market 45 

MACHINERY  PRODUCTS  :  Pricing  policies,  export  market ;  compressors 

and  pumps 51 

MAFFRY,  DR.  AUGUST :  Insurance  transactions  in  the  balance  of  inter- 
national payments  of  the  United  States;  cited  (n.) - 102 

MANCHUKUO:  Trust   laws   and    unfair   competition    legislation,   1937; 

summary 281 

MASS  PRODUCTION :  Pricing  policy,  export  market,  and  mass  produc- 
tion  83-86 

MEN'S  WEAR  INDUSTRY:  Pricing  policies,  export  market;  collars  and 

shirts 41 

MERCURY  CAJRTEL:  International  agreement  terminated,  1936 ^-      280 

MEXICO : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation;  summary: 

1936 269 

1937-38 281 

MINING  INDUSTRY :  Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States 100, 103 

MONOPOLY  {see  also  helow  References  to  Literature,  items  2,  17)  : 

International  price  discrimination  not  a  sign  of  monopoly 91 

Monopolistic  competition 74-80 

Monopoly  aspects  of  the  export  pricing  problem 74 

Monopoly  prices;  export  pricing  policies 31 

NETHERLANDS : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1936 269 

1937 281 

NEWFOUNDLAND :  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,  1938 ; 

summary 282 

NEW  YORK  TARIFF  REFORM  CLUB :  Report  on  comparative  domestic 

and  export  prices ;  cited  (n.) 9 

NEW  ZEALAND: 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1936 269 

1937 282 

NITRATE  INTERNATIONAL  CARTEL :  Expiration  of,  June  30,  1936 268  • 

NYASALAND:  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,  1937;  sum- 
mary  '■ V 2^ 

OFFICE  SUPPLIES   (see  also  Calculating  Machines,  Stationery  Goods, 
Typewriters)  : 

Pricing  policies,  export  market . 51 

PACIFIC  FOREST  INDUSTRIES : 

Federal  Trade  Commission  recommendations  for  readjustment  of  busi- 
ness of  Pacific  Forest  Industries,  an  export  trade  association ;  Janu- 
ary 27,  1940,  text 12&-30 

Federal  Trade  Commission's  recommendations  of  January  27,  1940; 

effect  of 138 

PAN  AMERICAN  COFFEE  BUREAU :  Establishment  of,  1936 268 

PANAMA  :  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,  1938 ;  summary—      282 

PAPER  SPECIALTIES  :  Pricing  policy,  export  market 40, 41, 46 

PARAGUAY:  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,  1936,  sum- 
mary       270 

PERU: 

Trust  laws  and  unfair-competition  legislation;  summary: 

1936 270 

1937 —      282 

257769 — 41— No.  6 21 


308  INDEX 

Page 
PETROLEUM  INDUSTRY:   Foreign  capital  invested    in  United   States, 

1937 101-102 

PHARMACEUTICAL  SPECIALTIES :  Pricing  policies,  export  market 55-56 

PHOSPHATE  INDUSTRY:  Foreign-owned  companies  control  in  United 

States 106 

PIPE  FITTINGS : 

British  and  American  thread-price  spread 21 

Pricing  policies,  exi)ort  market :  black  and  galvanized  iron  and  brass.        42 

PLUMBING  .FIXTURES  :  Pricing  policy,  export  market 61 

POLAND:  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation  1936;  summary..      270 
PORTUGAL : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation  ;  summary  : 

1937 270,  282 

1938 296 

PORTZELT,  PAUL :  Potash,  a  new  industry  making  satisfactory  progress ; 

cited    (n. ) 106 

POTASH  INDUSTRY : 

Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States 103 

Potash,  a  new  industry.    By  P.  Poftzelt ;  cited  (n.) 106 

United  States  industry  developed  since  1914 106 

PRICING  POLICY  FOR  THE  FOREIGN  MARKET.      {See  Export  Pric- 
ing Policies. ) 
PROFITABILITY  OF  EXPORT  TRADE.      [See  Export   Trade:   Profit- 
ability. ) 

PUBLIC  UTILITIES :  Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States,  1937 101 

PUMPS.     (See  Machinery  Products.) 

QUICKSILVER.      (See  Mercury  Cartel.) 

RADIO    MANUFACTURE:    Export    price    policy,    sets    and   phonograph 

branch 34 

RAILWAYS  :  Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States 102 

RAYON  INDUSTRY : 

Export  pricing  policy,  r.ayon  piece  goods 38 

Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States  companies 107 

Rayon  and  staple  fiber  yearbook;  edition  3,  1919;  cited  (n.) 107 

World  investments  in,  1929  and  1938;  cited 107 

RECIPROCAL  TRADE  AND/OR  TARIFF  AGREEMENTS  : 

Czechoslovakia  and  the  United  States,  1938 280 

United  States  and  other  countries,  1936-37 268 

REFERENCES  TO  LITERATURE : 

(1)  Callman,  Dr.  R.     Das  deutsche  Kartellrecht  (n.) x 

(2)  Chamberlin,  E.    Theory  of  monopolistic  competition  (n.) 78 

(3)  Dickens,  Paul  D.    American  direct  investments  in  foreign  coun- 

tries, 1936    (n.) 109 

Federal  Trade  Commission : 

(4)  Alleged  violation  of  antitrust  laws  by  combinations  formed 
al)i'oad;  report,  1926  (n.) 10,  IG 

(5)  Cooperation  in  American  export  trade;  report,  1916;  extracts-       113 

(6)  Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  1;  extracts  and  text 123,240 

(7)  Foreign  Trade  Series  No.  2;  cited  and  text 129,251 

(8)  Operation  of -Export  Trade  Act,  1918-40;  report,  cited  and 

text X,  111 

(9)  Haberler,  G.  von.     Theory  of  international  trade;  cited  (n.) 6,77 

(10)  Harkness.  M.  E.     References  on  the  Export  Trade  Act 297-300 

(11)  Kreps,  T.  J.     Export,  import,  domestic  prices  in  the  United  States, 

1926-30;   cited    (n.) x 

(12)  Liefmann,  Dr.  R.     Cartels,  combines  and  trusts;  cited x 

(13)  Maffry,  Dr.  A.     Insurance  transactions  in  the  balance  of  interna- 

tional payments  of  the  United  States;  cited  (n.) 102 

(14)  New  York  Tariff  Reform  Club.     Report  on  comparative  domes- 

tic and  export  prices ;  cited  (n.) 9 

(15)  Portzeldt,  P.     Potash,  a  new  industry  ;  cited  (n.) 106 

(16)  Rayon  and  Staple  Fiber  Yearbook,  edition  3,  1939;  cited  (».)___  107 

(17)  Robin.son,  Joan,  Economics  of  imperfect  competition  (n.) 78 


INDEX  309 

REFERENCES  TO  LITERATURE— Continued.  Page 

(18)  Taussig,  F,  W.,  Some  aspects  of  the  tariff  question  (n.) 5 

(19)  United  States,  Commerce  and  Labor  Departments.  Manufac- 
tured products  sold  in  foreign  markets  at  lower  rates  than  in 
American    (n.) 10 

(20)  United  States  Commerce  Department: 

Balance  of  international  payments  of  the  United  States,  1937  (n.)_      102 

(21)  Foreign  investments  in  the  United  States,  1937  (n.) 102 

(22)  Trade  Information  Bulletin  No.  834.  Insurance  transac- 
tions in  the  balance  of  international  payments  of  the  United 
States   (n.) 102 

(23)  United  States  Industrial  Commission  Reports,  vol.  13,  Foreign 

and  domestic  prices  of  American  products;  and  vol.  19  (n.) 7,8,9 

(24)  United  States  Mines  Bureau : 

Information  Circular  7034   (n.) 106 

(25)  Minerals  Yearbook    (n.) 106 

(26)  United  States  Treasury  Department.  Monthly  summary  of  com- 
merce and  finance,  Aug.  1900  (export  v.  domestic  price  policy)   (n.) 7 

(27)  Van  Zeeland,  P.,  Report  on  international  trade,  1938;  cited 280 

(28)  Viner,  Jacob.,  Dumping  (n.) 6,7,16,92 

RHODESIA :    Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,  1937 ;  sum- 
mary      282 

ROBINSON,  JOAN,  Ecbnomics  of  imperfect  competition;  cited  (n.) 78 

RUBBER  MANUFACTURE :    Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States, 

1937 100 

RUMANIA:    Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,  1936;  sum- 
mary        270 

SAN  SALVADOR:  Constitution  adopted  January  20,  1939 296 

SCRAP-IRON  INTERNATIONAL  CONVENTION,  1937 268 

SELLING  PROBLEM  (See  also  above  Export  Price  Policies)  : 

Foreign  and  domestic  markets 82 

SILVER  PRODUCERS  COMMITTEE:  Federal  Trade  Commission  reply, 
July  31,  1924,  to  queries  propounded  by  the  committee,  relating  to  a 

proposed  formation  of  an  export  association 125 

SODIUM  CHLORATE  INTERNATIONAL  CARTEL,  1937 268 

SPAIN : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1936 270 

1937 282 

STATIONERY  GOODS  AND  SUPPLIES :  Pricing  policies,  export  market-  40, 46, 

48    52    54 
STEEL  AND  IRON  INDUSTRY.     {8ee  Iron  and  Steel  Industry.) 

SUGAR  AGREEMENT,  1937 268 

SWITZERLAND : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation;  summary: 

1936 271 

1938 296 

TARIFFS,   INFLUENCE   OF 81 

TAUSSIG,  F.  W.    Some  aspects  of  the  tariff  question ;  cited  (n.) 5 

TEXTILE  INDUSTRY: 

Cotton  piece  goods.     (See  Cotton  Piece  Goods  Industry.) 
Cotton  staples.     (See  Cotton  Staples  Industry.) 

Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States,  1937 100 

Household  textiles.     (See  Household  Textile  Goods.) 
Rayon.     (See  Rayon  Industry.) 
THORP,  WILLARD: 

Foreword  to  Dickens  study  on  direct  foreign  investments  in  Ameri- 
can industry,  1937 : 86 

Foreword  for  Monograph  6 XIII 

TIN  RESTRICTION  AGREEMENT:  Revision  renewed  for  5-year  period 

January  1,  1937 ;  ratified  January  5,  1937 268,  280 

TOBACCO  MANUFACTURE: 

Cigarettes.     (See  Cigarette  Manufacture.) 

Foreign  capital  invested  in  United  States,  1937 101 


310  INDEX 

TRUST  LEGISLATION:  Page 

Trust  and  unfair  competition  legislation  in  foreign  countries,  1937- 
39:  summary: 

1937 , , , 264 

1938 , 275 

1939 ^ 290 

TURKEY : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1936 271 

1937 283 

inqg  _  _ _  __  296 

TYPEWRITER  MANUFACTURERS :  Pricing  policy,  export  market 49-50 

UNION  OF  SOUTH  AFRICA:  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legis- 
lation, 1937 ;  summary 282 

UNITED  STATES: 

BUREAU  OF  MINES : 

Information  Circular  7034;  cited  (n.) 106 

Minerals  Yearbook;  cited  (n.) 106 

COMMERCE  DEPARTMENT: 

Balance  of  international  payments  of  the  United  States,  1937; 

cited    (n.) 102 

Foreign  investments  in  the  United  States,  1937;  cited  (n.) 102 

Trade  Information  Bulletin  No.  834,  insurance  transactions  in  the 
balance  of  international  payments  of  the  United  States;  cited 

(n. ) 102 

COMMERCE  AND  LABOR  DEPARTMENT.    Manufactured  products 

sold  in  foreign  markets  atJower  rates  than  in  American ;  cited  (n.)_        10 
FEDERAL  TRADE  COMMISSION:  {See  alove  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission. ) 
Foreign  capital  invested  in   oe  United  States.  {See  above  Investments.) 
INDUSTRIAL  COMMISS  3N : 

Report,  volume  13,  Foreign  and  domestic  prices  of  American  prod- 
ucts; cited  (n.) 

Final  report,  volume  19;  cited  (n.) 7,8,9 

TREASURY  DEPARTMENT:  Monthly  summary  of  commerce   and 

finance,  August  1900;  cited  (n.) 7 

URUGUAY:  Trust  laws  and  unfair  competition  legislation,   1937;  sum- 
mary       283 

VAN  ZEELAND,  PAUL :  Report  on  international  trade,  1938 ;  cited 280 

VENEZUELA : 

Trust  laws  and  unfair-competition  legislation ;  summary : 

1936 271 

1939 296 

VINER,  JACOB: 
Dumping : 

A  problem  in  international  trade;  cited  (n.) 6,7,16 

Article  in  Encyclopedia  of  Social  Sciences,  volume  3,  page  276; 

cited 92 

WEBB-POMERENE  ACT   (April  10,  1918.     40  Stat.  516).     {See  Export 

Trade  Act. ) 
WEBB-POMERENE  ASSOCIATIONS.     {See  Export  Trade  Associations.) 
WILSON  TARIFF  ACT  (Aug.  27,  1894.     28  Stat.  509)  :  Amendments  of 
February  12,  1913  (sees.  73,  76,  77,  1894),  not  modified  by  Export  Trade 

Act,  text 249 

WOOD-PULP  PRODUCTS  INDUSTRY  :  Export  price  policy 33 

WRITING  PAPER  INDUSTRY  :  Pricing  policy,  export  market 40 

YUGOSLAVIA:  Trust    laws    and    unfair-competition    legislation,    1938; 

summary 1 296 

ZINC  CARTEL :  European  cartel,  reformation  of 280 

o 


^.u^fl?^  ''^^'-IC  LIBRARY 

,  Jllllfililili 

3  9999  06351  913  4