Skip to main content

Full text of "Investigation of concentration of economic power. Hearings before the Temporary National Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, Seventy-fifth Congress, third Session [-Seventy-sixth Congress, third Session] pursuant to Public Resolution no. 113 (Seventy-fifth Congress) authorizing and directing a select committee to make a full and complete study and investigation with respect to the concentration of economic power in, and financial control over, production of goods and services .."

See other formats


5SS^^53.522>SS5S2 


Northeastern  University 


School  of  Law 
Library 


77V^-v^^vWVv\^^^vVx^-W^V^ 


INVESTIGATION  OF  CONCENTRATION 
OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


HEARINGS 

BEFORE   THE 

TEMPORARY  NATIONAL  ECONOMIC  COMMITTEE 
CONGRESS  OF  THE  UNITED  STATES 

SEVENTY-SIXTH  CONGRESS 

THIRD  SESSION 
PURSUANT  TO 

Public  Resolution  No.  113 
(Seventy-fifth  Congress) 

AUTHORIZING  AND  DIRECTING  A  SELECT  COMMITTEE  10 
MAKE  A  FULL  AND  COMPLETE  STUDY  AND  INVESTIGA- 
TION WITH  RESPECT  TO  THE  CONCENTRATION  OF 
ECONOMIC  POWER  IN,  AND  FINANCIAL  CONTROL 
OVER,  PRODUCTION  AND  DISTRIBUTION 
OF    GOODS    AND  "services 


PART  26 


IRON  AND  STEEL  INDUSTRY 

UNITED  STATES  STEEL  CORPORATION  STUDIES 
PRICES  AND  COSTS 


JANUARY  23,  24,  AND  25,  1940 


Printed  for  the  use  of  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee 


UNITED   STATES 

GOVERNMENT  PRINTING  OFFICE 

WASHINGTON  :  1940 


RTHEASTERN  UNiVF.RSiTY  SCHOOlof  LAWDB' 


TEMPORARY  NATIONAL  ECONOMIC  COMMITTEE 

(Created  pursuant  to  Public  Res.  113,  75th  Cong.) 

JOSEPH  C.  O'MAHONEY,  Senator  from  Wyoming,  Chairman 

HATTON  W.  SUMNERS,  Representative  from  Texas,  Vice  Chairman 

WILLIAM  H.  KING,  Senator  from  Utah 

CLYDE  WILLIAMS,  Representative  from  Missouri 

B.  CARROLL  REECE,  Representative  from  Tennessee 

THURMAN  W.  ARNOLD,  Assistant  Attorney  General 

•WENDELL  BERGE,  Special  Assistant  to  the  AttorD«s:'<-*eneral 

Representing  the  Department  of  Justice 

JEROME  N.  FRANK.  Chairman 

•LEON  HENDERSON,  Commissioner 

Representing  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission 

GARLAND  S.  FERGUSON,  Commissioner  •      ^-*-^ 

•EWIN  L.  DAVIS,  Commissioner 
Representing  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  -_* 

ISADOR  LUBIN,  Commissioner  of  Labor  Statistics  CD 

•A.  FORD  HINRICHS,. Chief  Economist,  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  (jQ 

Representing  the  Department  of  Labor 
JOSEPH  J.  O'CONNELL,  JR.,  Special  Assistant  to  the  General  Counsel 
Representing  the  Department  of  the  Treasury 
SUMNER  T.  PIKE,  Business  Adviser  to  the  Secretary 
Representing  the  Department  of  Commerce 
JAMES  R.  BRACKETT,  Executive  Secretary 


CZi 


•Alternates. 


REPRINTED 
BY 

WILLIAM    S    HEIN    &  CO  ,  INC 

BUFFALO.    N.    Y. 
1968 


CONTENTS 


Testimony  of —  Page 

Appert,  Richard  H.,  attorney,  Rutherford,  N.  J 13650 

Bean,    Dr.    Louis,    Economic   Adviser,    Department   of   Agriculture, 

Washington,  D.  C 13719-13732 

deChazeau,  Dr.  Melvin  G.,  professor  at  the  University  of  Virginia, 

Charlottesville,  Va 13617-13648,  13671-13675 

Ezekiel,  Dr.  MordecaijEconomic  Adviser  to  the  Secretary,  Depart- 
ment of  Agriculture,  Washington,  D.  C 13676-13694 

Fairless,   Benjamin  F.,  president,  United  States  Steel  Corporation, 

New  York  City ..   13585-13586 

Lewis,  Harold  Gregg,  instructor  in  economics.  University  of  Chicago, 

Chicago,  lU 13650,  13738 

Taitel,  Martin,  Senior  Consulting  Economist,  Work  Projects  Adminis- 

.  tration,  Washington,  D.  C 13694-13709 

Yntenta,  Theodore  Otte,  professor  of  statistics.  University  of  Chicago, 

Chicago,  lU 13587-13616,  13650-13671,  13710,  13718,  13732-13741 

Summary  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  studies 1 3587 

Effects  of  price  reductions 13597 

Cash  costs 13600 

The  Corporation's  analysis  of  cost  in  relation  to  volume 13617 

Significance  of  the  cost  study  in  pricing  policy 13625 

United  States  Steel  Corporation's  analysis  of  demand  for  steel 13632 

Significance  of  concept  of  demand  for  industrial  price  policy 13634 

IN  MEMORIAM  SENATOR  WILLIAM  E.  BORAH 13648 

Discussion  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  studies 13650 

Relationship  between  prices,  demand,  and  costs 13655 

Analysis  of  operating  costs 13666 

Analysis  of  Dr.  Yntema's  statement  concerning  prices,  volume,  costs  and 

profits 13677 

Failure  of  high  prices  to  promote  business 13686 

Question  of  concerted  action  to  expand  production 13688 

United  States  Steel  Corporation  analysis  of  costs  in  relation  to  price  de- 
cision-making   13695 

.Examination  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  analyses 13720 

Schedule  and  summary  of  exhibits v 

Tuesday,  January  23,  1940---. 13585 

Wednesday,  January  24,  1940 13649 

Thursday,  January  25,  1940 13719 

Appendix , 13743 

Supplemental  data - 14127 

Index I 

in 


SCHEDULE  OF  EXHIBITS 


Number  and  summary  of  exhibits 


1409.  Book  of  charts  and  tables,  submitted  by  U.  S.  Steel  Cor- 

poration, as  follows:  financial,  costs,  prices,  capacity 
and  production,  labor,  miscellaneous 

1410.  Pamphlet,  submitted  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation,  entitled 

"Some  Factors  in  the  Prici;ig  of  Steel" 

1411.  Pamphlet,  submitted  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation,  entitled 

"A  Statistical  Analysis  of  the  Demand  for  Steel, 
1919-1938" . 

1412.  Pamphlet,  submitted  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation,  entitled 

"An  Analysis  of  Changes  in  the  Demand  for  Steel  and 
in  Steel  Prices,  193fr-1939" 

1413.  Pamphlet,  submitted  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation,  entitled 

"An  Analysis  of  the  Demand  for  Steel  in  the  Automo- 
bile Industry" 

1414.  Pamphlet,  submitted  bj^  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation,  entitled 

"An  Analysis  of  the  Demand  for  Steel  in  the  Railroad 
Industry" 

1415.  Pamphlet,  submitted  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation,  entitled 

"An  Analysis  of  the  Demand  for  Steel  in  the  Container 
Industry" 

1416.  Pamphlet,  submitted  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation,  entitled 

"An  Analysis  of  Steel  Prices,  Volume  and  Costs — Con- 
trolling Limitations  on  Price  Reductions" 

1417.  Pamphlet,  submitted  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation,  entitled 

"An  Analysis  of  Steel  Prices,  Volume  and  Costs  Con- 
trolling Limitations  on  Price  Reductions" 

1418.  Appears  in  Hearings,  Part  27. 

2180.  Pamphlet,  submitted  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation,  entitled 

"The  Distribution  of  Steel  to  Major  Consuming  In- 
dustries"  

2181.  Pamphlet,  submitted  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation,  entitled 

"Indexes  of  Mill-Net  Yields  on  Products  Shipped  by 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries" 

2182.  Pamphlet,  submitted  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation,  entitled 

"Improved  Quality  of  Steel  as  a  Price  Reduction" 

2183.  Chart:  Relation  of  industrial  production,  excluding  iroo 

and  steel,  to  steel  sales 

2184.  Chart:  Contrast  in  production-profit  computations 

2185.  Table:  Reconciliation  of  total  costs  before  bond  interest 

and  inter-company  items  in  "Analysis"  and  registra- 
tion statement,  1935-37 — ^U.  S.  Steel  Corporation. 

Table:  Comparison  of  break -down  of  lumped  costs  in  the 
"Analysis"  and  in  registration  statement,  1935-37- — 
U.  S.  Steel  Corporation. 

Table:  Additions  to  reserves  charged  to  cost  of  goods 
sold,  etc.,   1935-37— U.  S.  Steel  Corporation. 

Table:  Taxes  other  than  Federal  income  and  Social  Secu- 
rity taxes,  1927-38— U.  S.  Steel  Corporation. 

Table:  Taxes  other  than  Federal  income  and  Social  Secu- 
rity taxes,  1927-38 — Recomputed  "fixed"  and  "vari- 
able" costs — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation. 

Table:  Maintenance  and  repairs, '1927-38 — U.  S.  Steel 
Corporation. 

Table:  Stripping  and  development  expenses,  1927-38 — 
U.  S.  St^el  Corporation 


Intro- 
duced at 
page— 


(') 

(0 

(') 
(') 
(') 
(') 
n) 

0) 

(') 

13586 

13586 

13586 

13680 
13695 


Appears 


13743 
13893 

13913 

13942 

13981 

13999 

14016 

14032 

14082 

14095 

14101 

14109 

14119 
14120 


13701  I  14121 


See  Hearings,  Part  I 


See  also  p.  13.585,  infra. 


VI 


CONTENTS 
SCHEDULE  OF  EXHIBITS— Continued 


Number  and  sumn^ary  of  exhibits 

Intro- 
duced at 
page- 

Appears 
on  page— 

2186.  Chart:  Price  of  tin  plate  and  of  canned  goods,  1923-1938. 
2187    Chart"  The  net  regression  of  volume  on  price 

13726 
13729 

13731 

14124 
14125 

2188.  Chart:  Indexes  of  wholesale  prices  of  iron  and  steel  and 
other  goods,  1919-1938 

14126 

SUPPLEMENTAL  DATA 

Unnumbered.  Telegrams,  dated  October  10,  1939,  from  Harry 
Moreland,  vice  president.   Great  Lakes  Pipe 
Line  Co.,  to  James  Brackett,  secretary  of  the 
Committee,  authenticating  certain  statements 
made  by   Mr.   Eugene  Orvis  in  his  prepared 
statement,  admitted  to  the  record  as  "Exhibit 
No.  1293"  and  included  in  Hearings,  Part  16, 
appendix,  p.  9330 

14127 

INVESTIGATION  OF  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


TUESDAY,  JANUARY  23,  1940 

United  States  Senate, 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee, 

Washington,  D.  C. 

The  committee  met  at  10:35  a.  m.,  pursuant  to  call  of  the  chair- 
man, in  the  Caucus  Room,  Senate  Office  Building,  Senator  William 
H.  King,  Utah,  presiding. 

Present:  Senator  lOng  (acting  chairman);  Messrs.  Hiarichs, 
O'Connell,  and  Brackett. 

Present  also:  Willis  Ballinger  and  Walter  B.  Wooden,  represent- 
ing the  Federal  Trade  Commission;  John  V.  W.  Reynders,  represent- 
ing the  Department  of  Commerce;  A.  H.  Feller,  representing  the 
Department  of  Justice;  Dr.  Theodore  J.  Kreps,  economic  adviser  to 
the  committee. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Dr.  Kreps,  are  you  ready  to  proceed? 

Dr.  Kreps.  Yes,  sir. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Mr.  Fairless,  come  forward,  please.  You 
were  sworn  here  before  as  a  witness.     You  may  proceed,  Dr.  Kreps. 

TESTIMONY    OF   BENJAMIN   F.    FAIRLESS,    PRESIDENT,    UNITED 
STATES  STEEL  CORPORATION,  NEW  YORK  CITY 

Dr.  Kreps.  Mr.  Fairless,  will  you  make  your  statement,  please? 

Mr.  Fairless.  Mr.  Chairman,  at  the  hearing  held  on  November  8, 
1939,  I  submitted  to  the  committee  certain  charts  and  pamphlets 
which  were  marked  "Exhibits  Nos.  1409  to  1418,"  inclusive.^  I  am 
informed  that  these  exhibits  may  now  form  a  part  of  the  record  of 
the  committee,  and,  accordingly,  I  offer  these  exhibits  for  that  pur- 
pose, together  with  3  additional  pamphlets  and  13  additional  charts, 
which  have  been,  heretofore  given  to  Dr.  Kreps. 

("Exhibits  Nos.  1409  to  1417,"  inclusive,  are  included  in  the  ap- 
pendix on  pp.  13743-14082.  "Exhibit  No.  1418"  appears  in  Hearings, 
Part  27,  appendix,  p.  14:i9.) 

These  additional  pamphlets  are  entitled  "The  Distribution  of  Steel 
to  Major  Consuming  Industries,"  "Indexes  of  Mill-Net  Yields  on 
Products  Shipped  by  United  States  Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries," 
and  "Improved  Quality  of  Steel  as  a  Price  Reduction."  The  13 
additional  charts  should  be  included  in  the  book  of  charts,  designated 
as  "Exhibit  No.  1409."  ^ 

Dr.  Kreps.  Mr.  Chairman,  I  suggest  that  these  exhibits  be  placed 
into  the  record  as  indicated  by  Mr.  lairless. 

'  See  Hearings,  Part  20,  p.  10803. 

'  The  13  additional  charts  are  included  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409,"  appendix,  p.  13743. 


13586  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Acting  Chairman  King.  They  may  be  so  received  and  placed  in 
the  record. 

(The  three  pamphlets  referred  to  were  marked  "Exhibits  Nos. 
2080,  2181,  and  2182,"  respectively,  and  are  included  in  the  appendix 
on  pp.  14095,  14101  and  14109.) 

Mr.  Fairless.  I  should  like,  Mr.  Chairman,  to  say  a  few  words 
about  these  various  pamphlets  and  charts  which  have  been  submitted 
to  the  committee  by  the  Steel  Corporation.  From  the  outset,  we  have 
understood  that  it  was  the  pm-pose  of  the  T.  N.  E.  C.  to  obtain  the 
material  facts  about  the  steel  industry  as  a  part  of  the  committee's 
objective  inquiry  into  American  business.  The  Steel  Corporation  has 
tried  to  the  best  of  its  ability  to  cooperate  with  the  committee  to  this 
end.  Accordingly,  we  organized  a  special  T.  N.  E.  C.  group,  consist- 
ing of  30  or  more  individuals.  Some  were  employees  of  the  Corpora- 
tion; some  were  economists  and  graduate  students  in  economics  em- 
ployed by  the  Corporation  for  this  purpose;  and  some  were  lawyers 
assigned  to  this  work  by  Governor  Miller  and  Mr.  Olds,  two  of  our 
directors,  from  their  respective  law  offices.  This  group  over  a  period 
of  more  than  a  year  and  a  half  has  conducted  various  studies,  the  re- 
sults of  which  are  contained  in  these  papers.  The  work,  of  an  economic 
nature,  was  imder  the  direction  of  Dr.  Theodore  O.  Yntema,  of  the 
University  of  Chicago,  who  is  here  today  and  is  prepared  to  explain 
to  the  committee  the  various  studies  made  mider  his  direction. 

On  behalf  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  I  should  like  to 
express  our  appreciation  of  your  admission  into  the  record  of  these 
various  papers,  which  I  hope  wiU  be  of  aid  to  the  committee  in  its 
consideration  of  the  topics  discussed  therein. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  Mr.  Chairman,  could  the  Federal  Trade  Commis- 
sion make  the  request  that  the  pamphlet  on  the  basing-point  system  ^ 
not  be  released  to  the  press  until  our  reply  to  it  accompanies  it?  ^ 

Acting  Chairman  King.  What  are  your  views  about  that,  Dr. 
Kreps? 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  think  that  would  be  fair. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Do  yoii  have  any  objection  to  that,  Mr. 
Fairless? 

Mr.  Fairless.  No  objection. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Granted. 

Dr.  Kreps.  That  is  all.  Mr.  Fairless  will  be  called  back  later  in 
the  hearing. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  The  committee  may  not  be  able  to  read 
those  records  during  this  hearing,  I  mean  today,  but  I  think  we  shall 
before  we'  conclude  our  labors. 

Dr.  Kreps.  These  have  all  been  submitted  to  the  members  of  the 
committee  as  well  as  to  the  members  of  the  staff. 

I  would  like  next  to  call  Prof.  Theodore  Ottc  Yntema  to  take  the 
stand. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Doctor,  will  you  come  forward?  Will  you 
hold  up  your  right  hand  and  be  sworn? 

Do  you  .solemnly  swear  that  the  testimony  you  will  give  in  this 
hearing  shall  be  the  truth,  the  whole  truth,  and  nothing  but  the  truth, 
so  help  you  God? 

1  "Exhibit  No.  1418." 

'  Mr.  Ballinper  refers  to  "An  Analysis  of  the  Basing  Point  System  of  pelivered  Prices  as  Presented  by 
United  State*  Steel  Corporation  in  *E.\hibits  Nos.  1110  and  1418'  by  Walter  B.  Wooden,  Assistant  Chief 
Counsel,  and  Hugh  E.  Wbitt ,  Examiner  Tederal  Trade  Commission,"  admitted  to  the  record  as  "Exhibit 
No.  2242"  and  appearing  in  Hearings,  Part  27. 


CONGENTKATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWER        13587 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  do. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  may  proceed. 

TESTIMONY  OF  DR.   THEODORE   OTTE  YNTEMA,   PROFESSOR  OF 
STATISTICS,   UNIVERSITY   OF  CHICAGO,   CHICAGO,  ILL. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Dr.  Yntema,  for  the  pm-pose  of  the  record,  will  you 
state  your  full  name  and  address,  please? 

Dr.  Yntema.  My  name  is  Theodore  Otte  Yntema.  My  address  is 
1154  East  Fifty-sixth  Street,  Chicago,  111. 

t)Ti  Kreps.  You  are  professor  of  statistics  in  the  School  of  Business 
of  the  University  of  Chicago,  is  that  correct? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct. 

'Dr.  Kreps.  And  director  of  research  in  the  Cowles  Commission  for 
Research  in  Economics,  an  institution  affihated  with  the  University 
of  Chicago? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct. 

Dr.  'Kreps.  You  are  also  a  certified  public  accountant? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct, 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  have  taught  accounting  for  several  years  at  the 
University  of  Chicago? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Since  what  period  have  you  been  associated  with  the 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  as  a  consulting  economist? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Since  July  1938. 

Dr.  Kreps.  How  much  of  your  time  have  you  devoted  to  the 
studies  which  have  been  submitted  here  by  Mr.  Fairless? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  have  devoted  over  half  of  my  time  to  the  preparation 
of  these  studies. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Have  you  had  assistance? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes.  Under  my  supervision  I  had  a  special  research 
section,  consisting  of  economists,  graduate  students  and  others. 

Dr.  Keeps.  A  number  of  these  had  already  made  intensive  studies 
of  the  steel  industry  before  they  worked  on  your  staff? 

Dr.  Yntema.  One  of  these  members  had. 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  believe  you  have  a  brief  summarj^  of  your  analysis 
which  you  would  like  to  present  to  the  committee  entitled  "Factors 
Affecting  the  Demand  for  Steel  and  the  Relation  of  Steel  Prices  to 
Costs"? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct. 

Dr.  Keeps.  You  may  proceed. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Proceed,  Doctor. 

summaey  of  united  states  steel  coepoeation  studies 

Dr.  Yntema.  In  summarizing  these  studies,  it  will  be  necessary  for 
me  to  pass  over  many  interesting  and  important  details,  to  confine 
myself  to  a  rather  cursory  statement  of  the  facts  and  the  inferences  to 
be  drawn  from  them,  and  to  omit  at  many  points  the  qualifications 
which  would  be  desirable  if  there  were  time  for  them. 

This  committee  has  evidenced  a  deep  interest  in  the  relation  of 
steel  prices  to  production  and  employment  in  the  steel  industry. 
Recognizing  the  importance  of  this  problem  and  the  committee's 
interest  in  it,  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  has  prepared  and 


13588  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

submitted  to  the  committee  a  number  of  studies  dealing  with  this 
subject.  It  is  our  hope  that  the  members  of  the  committee  may  find 
them  helpful  in  their  deliberations.  We  welcome  criticism  of  these 
studies  and  hope  that  out  of  the  discussion  there  may  come  a  better  un- 
derstanding of  the  important  problems  to  which  they  relate. 

These  studies  do  not,  of  course,  answer  all  the  questions  relating  to 
price  flexibility  in  durable  goods,  but  they  do,  we  believe,  present 
factual  evidence  illuminating  some  aspects  of  the  problem. 

The  basic  questions  to  which  our  studies  were  addressed  are  these: 

1.  To  what  extent  will  the  production  and  sale  of  steel  respond  to 
changes  in  the  price  of  steel? 

2.  To  what  extent  do  costs  vary  with  volume  of  production? 

3.  How  far,  if  at  all,  is  it  feasible  for  the  steel  industry  to  achieve 
additional  sales,  production  and  employment  in  depression  by  reduc- 
tion of  prices? 

In  other  words,  is  it  possible  for  the  steel  industry  to  achieve  fuller 
utihzation  of  its  productive  facOities  and  thus  greater  employment  by 
means  of  price  reductions  in  periods  of  low  demand? 

An  analysis  of  the  evidence  available  to  us  leads  to  these  conclusions: 

1.  The  quantity  of  steel  that  can  be  sold  is  relatively  unresponsive 
to  changes  in  the  level  of  steel  prices.  In  other  words,  the  demand  for 
steel  is  inelastic.  A  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel,  therefore,  will 
bring  only  a  small  increase  in  its  consumption.  The  fluctuations  in 
the  production  of  steel  have  been  due  primarily  to  shifts  in  demand 
caused  by  changes  in  general  business  activity,  consumers'  income 
and  industrial  profits.  In  comparison  with  these  factors,  the  price 
of  steel  has  been  a  minor  influence  on  the  quantity  of  steel  sold. 

2.  The  reduction  in  average  costs  resulting  from  increased  output 
is  much  less  than  the  reduction  in  prices  which  is  necessary  to  induce 
such  increase  in  output.  All  but  a  small  percentage  of  the  costs  of 
producing  steel,  in  good  times  and  bad,  are  out-of-pocket  expenditures. 
Unless  wages  and  other  costs  could  have  been  further  reduced  in  de- 
pression, a  substantially  lower  price  level  for  steel  during  the  past  10 
years  would  have  brought  general  bankruptcy  in  the  industry. 

In  view  of  these  facts,  full  production  and  employment  cannot  be 
maintained  in  the  steel  industry  during  depression  by  means  of 
reduction  in  steel  prices. 

These  conclusions  are  based  on  the  assumption  of  a  reduction  only 
in  the  price  of  steel.  It  has  often  been  pointed  out  that  the  inelas- 
ticity of  demand  for  individual  durable  goods  does  not  afford  an 
adequate  basis  for  demonstrating  the  inelasticity  of  demand  for  dur- 
able goods  in  the  aggregate.  This  we  recognize.  What  would  happen 
to  production  and  employment  if  there  were  greater  cyclical  flexibility 
in  the  prices  of  all  durable  goods  is  a  most  difficult  and  perplexing 
question.  Although  we  have  given  the  matter  much  study,  we  have 
not  been  able  to  reach  conclusions  which  we  can  establish  beyond 
reasonable  doubt.  We  have  found  that  others  better  qualified  to 
deal  with  this  problem  have  had  the  same  experience,  and  that  there 
is  on  the  part  of  many  economists  honest  doubt  as  to  the  efficacy  of 
price  flexibility  as  a  cure  for  depressions.  There  is,  however,  general 
recognition  that  the  existent  inflexibilty  in  costs,  particularly  in  wages, 
taxes,  and  transportation  charges,  aU  of  which  are  subject  in  piM:  r 
or  less  degree  to  Government  regulation  or  influence,  is  so  great  as 
to  preclude  any  considerable  increase  in  the  flexibility  of  the  prices  of 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13589 

finished  products.  Unless  the  costs  of  producing  durable  goods  are 
flexible,  it  is  idle  to  talk  of  flexibility  in  their  prices. 

In  analyzing  the  demand  for  steel  we  approached  the  problem  in 
two  ways.  First,  we  undertook  to  study  the  demand  for  steel  from 
major  consuming  industries.  On  the  basis  of  rough  estimates  of  the 
elasticity  of  demand  for  the  products  of  these  industries  and  the 
relative  proportion  of  steel  cost  to  the  prices  of  their  products,  it  was 
possible  to  discover  approximately  the  effect  of  changes  in  steel  prices 
upon  the  prices  and  consumption  of  the  finished  products  made  from 
steel  and  thus  upon  the  consumption  of  steel  in  these  industries.  In 
the  second  place,  we  made  a  statistical  analysis  of  the.  data  over  the 
past  20  years  to  discover  the  relation  of  steel  production  to  steel 
prices  and  other  factors  determining  demand,  and  thereby  to  ascer- 
tain the  relative  importance  of  price  as  a  factor  influencing  the 
quantity  of  steel  produced  and  sold. 

During  the  last  15  years  the  automobile,  railroad,  and  container 
industries  have  consumed  almost  40  percent  of  the  steel  produced  in 
this  country.  These  industries  represent  three  different  types  of 
steel  consmners,  one  using  steel  as  a  raw  material  in  the  manufacture 
of  a  consumer's  dm-able  good,  another  using  steel  in  the  form  of  plant 
and  equipment,  and  the  third  using  steel  as  a  raw  material  in  the 
manufactm-e  of  a  consumer's  perishable  good. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Pardon  me.  Doctor,  but  have  you  broken 
down  that  40  percent  to  which  you  have  just  referred,  to  determine 
what  percentage  of  it  was  required  by  the  railroads? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  haven't  the  percentage  figure  handy.  Senator, 
but  we  have  just  submitted  to  the  committee  a  special  study,  "The 
Distribution  of  Steel  to  Major  Consuming  Industries."  ^ 

Acting  Chairman  King.  And  that  would  show  the  amount  which 
was  consumed  by  the  railroads,  would  it? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes,  sir;  that  shows,  to  the  best  of  our  abiUty  to  make 
such  an  estimate,  the  amount  consumed  by  the  railroads. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Proceed. 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  automobile  industry:  The  automobile  industry 
has  been  the  largest  single  consumer  of  steel  for  5  of  the  last  6  years, 
taking  between  one-fourth  and  one-sixth  of  the  total  of  all  hot-rolled 
steel  products. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  They  took  between  one-fourth  and  one- 
sixth  of  the  40  percent  which  you  have  attributed  to  the  automobile 
and  the  railroad  industries  and  left  the  residue,  of  about  30  percent 
or  more^  to  the  railroads? 

Dr.  \  NTEMA.  There  are  three  industries  whose  consumption  com- 
prises the  40  percent  of  the  total  production:  The  automobile,  railroad, 
and  container  industries. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Oh,  yes. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Although  it  has  had  a  long-term  upward  trend,  auto- 
mobile production  has  been  subject  to  severe  cyclical  fluctuations.  In 
1929,  approximately  5.6  milUon  cars  were  produced.  In  1932,  pro- 
duction slumped  to  about  1.4  milUon,  only  25  percent  of  the  1929 
production.  By  1937,  production  had  risen  to  approximately  5,000,- 
030  cars,  more  than  three  times  the  volume  in  1932. 

The  reasons  for  these  wide  fluctuations  in  automobile  production 
were  carefully  analyzed  by  C.  F.  Roos  and  Victor  von  Szehski  in  a 

:  "Exhibit  No.  2180,"  appendix,  p.  14095. 


13590  CONCENTllATION  OF  ECM3NOMIC  POWER 

study  made  for  General  Motors  Corporation.  They  found  that  the 
number  of  new  cars  sold  in  any  year  was  dependent  on  (1)  the  national 
income;  (2)  the  number  of  cars  in  operation;  (3)  the  age  distribution 
of  cars  in  operation;  (4)  the  scrapping  rate;  (5)  the  price;  and  (6) 
other  factors,  including  used-car  allowance,  financing  terms,  operating 
cost,  and  dealers'  used-car  stocks.  Taking  all  these  factors  into 
account,  they  showed  that  a  1 -percent  reduction  in  the  price  of  new 
passenger  cars  would  cause  approximately  a  1.5-percent  increase  in 
the  number  of  cars  sold.  They  concluded  that  the  effect  of  price 
changes  on  the  number  of  cars  sold  was  overshadowed  by  the  in- 
fluence of  changes  in  national  income,  and  that  the  changes  in  price 
could  not  level  out  the  sharp  fluctations  in  production  of  automobiles. 

The  railroad  industry:  For  many  years  the  railroad  industry 
ranked  first  as  a  consumer  of  steel.  In  1926,  railroads  consunried 
approximately  7.6  million  tons  of  hot-rolled  finished  products,  which 
represented  about  21.6  percent  of  that  year's  total  production.  During 
the  last  10  years,  this  industry's  purchases  of  steel  have  decHned  abso- 
lutely and  relatively. 

The  cyclical  fluctuations  in  railroad  purchases  of  steel  are  particu- 
larly marked.  In  1932,  the  railroads  took  approximately  1,000,000 
tons  of  steel,  while  in  1937,  a  relatively  good  year,  they  purchased 
4.1  million  tons,  still  much  less  than  their  predepression  consumption. 

The  serious  plight  of  the  railroads  is  common  knowledge.  They 
have  suffered  both  from  a  downward  trend  in  operation  and  from  the 
severity  of  the  recent  depression.  As  a  consequence,  the  need  for 
new  equipment  has  declined  and  the  revenues  in>many  cases  have  been 
inadequate  for  maintenance  and  replacement  of  existing  facilities  • 

The  cyclical  fluctuations  in  railroad  traffic  have  been  closely  related 
to  changes  in  the  national  income  and  in  industrial  production,  while 
the  downward  trend  has  been  due  primarily  to  competition  from 
alternative  means  of  transportation. 

Acting  Chairman  Kino.  You  refer  to  trucks,  I  suppose,  and  water 
transportation? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes,  trucks  and  water  transportation;  also  pipe-line 
transportation. 

Capital  expenditures  for  rolling  stock  and  other  equipment  requiring 
steel  are  ultimately  dependent  upon  the  demand  for  rail  transportation 
but  in  the  short  run  they  are  determined  by  the  pressure  of  current 
traffic  on  existing  facilities  and  by  the  funds  available  for  capital 
outlays.  Hence,  when  the  demand  for  railroad  services  declines,  and 
only  a  part  of  the  rolling  stock  and  other  equipment  is  needed^  to 
furnish  all  the  services  required,  there  is  obviously  less  need  for  capital 
expenditures. 

Tluis,  capital  expenditures  for  equipment  dropped  from  about 
§328,000,000  in  1930  to  about  $15,000,000  in  19^3,  a  decline  of  about 
95  percent.  Purchases  of  steel  for  maintenance  purposes-have,  how- 
ever, been  more  closely  related  to  the  volume  of  traffic  currently 
handled  by  the  railroads,  since  some  degree  of  maintenance  must 
continue  even  in  depression.  Nonetheless,  declining  traffic  and 
lower  revenues  have  drastically  reduced  total  steel  purchases  by  the 
railroads. 

The  container  industry:  Consumption  of  steel  by  the  container 
industry  (whose  principal  product  is  the  tin  can,  a  consumers'  per- 
ishable good)  has.  shown  a  substantial  upward  trend  since  1923.     In 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13591 

that  year  the  container  industry  took  3.6  percent  of  the  total  finished 
rolled  steel,  but  since  1932  it  has  taken  on  the  average  more  than  8 
percent  of  the  total  output.  In  1938,  it  ranked  third  among  consum- 
ing industries,  accounting  for  9.9  percent  of  the  total  output  of  steel. 
While  the  annual  average  consumption  of  steel  by  the  contamer  indus- 
try was  1.4  million  gross  tons  during  the  period  from  1923  to  1929,  in 
the  period  from  1932  to  1938  its  annual  consumption  averaged  about 
1.9  million  gross  tons,  which  is  rouglily  an  increase  of  36  percent. 
This  relative  stability  of  the  container  industry  during  depression  peri- 
ods is  further  shown  by  the  fact  that  tin-plate  production  ranged 
from  about  60  to  90  percent  of  capacity  during  the  depression,  while 
total  steel  production  varied  from  about  15  percent  to  60  percent  of 
capacity. 

Although  the  demand  for  products  packed  in  tin  cans  is  largely  de- 
pendent upon  consumers'  income,  the  relatively  greater  stability  of 
tin-plate  production  in  depression  periods  is  due  primarily  to  the  fact 
that  the  majority  of  containers  made  from  tin  plate  are  used  for  food 
products.  Being  a  perishable  necessity,  food  must  be  purchased  even 
in  depression  times,  whereas  purchases  of  more  durable  products  may 
be  postponed.  The  comparative  stability  of  tin-plate  production 
arises  from  this  fact. 

The  decline  in  consum.ption  of  steel  by  the  container  industry  from 
1929  to  1932  was  further  reduced  by  the  underlying  upward  trend  in 
tin-can  consumption,  due  largely  to  the  increasing  use  of  tin  cans  to 
pack  additional  kinds  of  foods  and  other  products. 

Other  investigations  have  shown  that  the  demand  for  various  agri- 
cultural products  is  inelastic.  This  is  to  say  that  a  given  percentage 
price  reduction  does  not  produce  a  corresponding  percentage  increase 
in  consumption.  The  available  data  also  indicate  that  fluctuations 
in  the  total  consumption  of  canned  food  products  have  had  little  net 
relation  to  fluctuations  in  canned  food  prices  or  to  fluctuations  in  the 
ratio  of  canned  food  prices  to  other  food  prices.  From  these  facts, 
it  is  reasonable  to  infer  that  the  demand  for  canned  food  products  has 
a  low  elasticity. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  have  no  figures  showing  the  curve  of 
upward  or  downward  steel  consumption  in  building  operations,  have 
you? 

Dr.  Yntema.  We  have  that  evidence  in  this  pamphlet  which  we 
submitted  to  the  committee  this  morning,  "The  Distribution  of  Steel 
to  Major  Consuming  Industries."  * 

Acting  Chairman  King.  All  right;  proceed, 

Dr.  Yntema.  Other  steel-consuming  industries':  We  have  not 
examined  in  detail  the  demand  for  steel  in  other  major  steel-consuming 
industries.  In  nearly  all  cases  the  products  of  these  industries  are 
durable  goods  subject  to  great  cyclical  fluctuations  in  demand. 
Many  of  them  are  producers'  goods,  vt^hich  are  utilized  in  the  pro- 
duction of  other  goods  and  services.  In  such  cases,  the  cost  of  the 
product  made  from  steel  is  not  usually  a  large  proportion  of  the  value 
of  the  goods  and  services  produced  by  the  industries  using  these 
products  made  from  steel.  Consequently,  there  is  good  reason  to 
believe  that  the  demand  for  the  products  of  these  industries  is  generally 
not  very  elastic  and  in  many  cases  is  inelastic. 

1  "Exhibit  No.  2180,"  appendix,  p.  14095. 


13592  CONCENTRATION  OF  E<X>NOMIC  t»OWER 

The  relations  of  the  cost  of  steel  to  the  price  of  the  finished  product: 
The  demand  for  steel  is  derived  from  the  demand  for  the  services 
rendered  by  steel  products,  or,  more  directly,  from  the  demand  for  the 
finished  products  themselves.  A  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel,  if 
passed  on,  willl  reduce  the  price  of  the  finished  product.  In  greater 
or  less  degree,  this  will  increase  the  consumption  of  the  product  and, 
thus,  the  consumption  of  steel  used  in  its  manufacture.  Furthermore, 
a  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel  may  perhaps  increase  the  use  of  steel 
per  miit  of  finished  product.  In  each  of  these  cases,  however,  the 
critical  question  is,  how  much? 

The  percentage  decrease  in  the  price  of  a  finished  product  made 
possible  by  a  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel  depends  upon  the  propor- 
tion of  the  cost  of  steel  to  the  value  of  the  finished  product.  What  is 
this  proportion? 

In  the  case  of  low-priced  automobiles,  the  cost  of  steel  is  about  10 
percent  of  the  delivered  price.  This  percentage  would  be  lower  for  a 
more  expensive  automobile.  For  a  representative  list  of  canned  food 
products,  the  cost  of  tin  plate  per  can  varied  from  3.4  to  13.9 
percent  of  the  retail  price  of  such  food  products.  The  cost  of  steel 
consumed  by  the  railroads  is  estimated  to  average  only  about  5 
percent  of  the  value  of  transportation  services  furnished  by  them. 
In  the  construction  industry,  steel  costs  range  from  4  percent  of  the 
total  cost  of  a  frame  house  to  as  much  as  30  percent  of  the  total  cost 
of  a  steel  bridge.  For  a  modern  automatic  packaging  machine,  the 
steel  cost  cc  Tiponent  was  found  to  be  less  than  2  percent  of  the  selling 
price.  Ext  .'eme  examples  may  be  cited  showing  a  very  high  or  very 
low  ratio  of  the  cost  of  steel  to  the  price  of  the  finished  product,  but 
10  percent  appears  to  be  a  reasonably  typical  proportion. 

On  this  basis,  a  10-percent  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel  would 
correspond  to  a  1-percent  reduction  in  the  price  of  the  finished  product 
made  from  steel. 

Since  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  the  finished  products  of  most 
steel-consuming  industries  is  low,  probably  less  than  1  or  2,  a  1 -percent 
decrease  in  the  price  of  the  product  would  not  increase  the  quantity 
sold  by  more  than  1  or  2  percent.  If  other  conditions  affecting  demand 
and  costs  remain  the  same,  a  10-percent  reduction  in  the  price  of 
steel  Would  not  increase  the  consumption  of  steel  by  more  than  1  or  2 
percent  through  its  effect  upon  the  price  of  the  finished  product. 

Substitution  of  steel  for  other  materials:  In  the  industries  studied, 
price  is  generally  not  an  important  factor  in  the  substitution  of  steel 
for  other  products.  The  physical  characteristics  of  steel,  especially 
its  great  tensile  strength  and  durability  in  comparison  with  other 
materials,  sharply  limit  the  possible  uses  of  substitutes.  In  the  case 
of  tin  cans,  there  is  some  degree  of  substitutability  between  containers 
made  of  tin  plate  and  those  made  of  glass.  Even  in  this  case  however 
numerous  factors  limit  the  possibility  of  substitution  in  response  to 
price  changes. 

The  amount  of  steel  used  in  the  finished  product:  In  the  automobile 
industry,  there  was  for  a  number  of  years  an  increasing  use  of  steel 
per  car  due  to  the  growing  popularity  of  closed  and  heavier  models, 
and  the  changes  in  construction  in  the  interests  of  safety.  These 
developments,  however,  cannot  be  attributed  to  steel  prices.  In 
most  cases,  technical  considerations  determine,  within  rather  rigid 
limits,    the  qiiantity  of  steel   employed  in  any  particular  product. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13593 

Although  some  shght  increase  in  the  weight  of  steel  used  per  unit  of 
product  may  result  from  a  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel,  this  effect 
is  certainly  not  of  substantial  proportions. 

The  elasticity  of  the  demand  for  steel:  From  the  discussion  thus  far, 
it  is  apparent  that  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  is  not  very  responsive  to 
changes  in  the  level  of  steel  prices. 

Let  m.e  interpolate  here,  to  point  out  that  I  am  talking  about  the 
responsiveness  of  the  total  quantity  of  steei  sold  by  the  industry,  in 
response  to  the  changes  in  steel  prices. 

To  ro.ake  an  estimate  of  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  in  the 
various  consum.ing  industries,  we  must  take  into  account,  first,  the 
elasticity  of  demand  for  the  products  made  from  steel;  second,  the 
proportion  of  steel  cost  to  the  price  of  the  finished  product;  third,  the 
substitutability  of  steel  for  other  materials;  and,  fourth,  the  possibility 
of  increasing  the  amount  of  steel  in  the  finished  product.  In  apprais- 
ing these  factors,  we  have  found  that  the  elasticity  of  dem.and  for  the 
products  made  from  steel  is  generally  rather  low,  in  m.ost  instances, 
probably  not  greater  than  1  or  2 ;  that  the  proportion  of  steel  cost  to 
the  price  of  the  finished  product  is,  on  the  average,  in  the  neighborhood 
of  10  percent. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Say  that  again.     I  didn't  get  it. 

Dr.  Yntema.  And  that  the  proportion  of  steel  cost  to  the  price  of 
the  finished  product  is,  on  the  average,  in  the  neighborhood  of  10 
percent. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Going  down? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  a  very  rough  approximation. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  But  that  is  going  down  to  10  percent? 

Dr.  Yntema.  It  ranges  usually  from  3  to  30  percent  but  10  per- 
cent is  a  roughly  typical  figure  that  we  might  take  for  discussion. 

To  continue:  The  possibilities  of  substitution  of  steel  for  other  mate- 
rials and  of  increasing  the  amount  of  steel  in  the  finished  product  are 
of  relatively  minor  importance. 

From  the  evidence,  it  is  safe  to  conclude  that  the  demand  for  steel 
is  inelastic,  that  is,  that  a  given  percentage  reduction  in  price  wjll  not 
bring  about  as  large  a  percentage  increase  in  the  quantity  sold.  Al- 
though any  such  estimate  is  subject  to  a  wide  margin  of  error  it 
seems  probable  that  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  is  not  greater 
than  0.3  or  0.4,  that  is,  that  a  10  percent  reduction  in  price  would 
not  increase  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  by  more  than  3  or  4  percent. 

In  concluding  this  part  of  our  discussion,  it  should  be  pointed  out 
that  these  estimates  are  based  upon  the  assumption  that  other  prices 
and  other  factors  affecting  the  demand  for  steel  remain  the  same. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  Dr.  Yntema,  how  many  industries  did  you 
analyze  that  use  steel?     I  mean  in  testing  this  elasticity  of  demand? 

Dr.  Yntema.  We  analyzed  in  some  detail  these  three  to  which  I 
have  referred. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  Representing  about  40  percent;  the  other  60  per- 
cent, you  didn't  look  into? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  we  investigated  briefly  the  construction  in- 
dustry and  found  the  problems  there  were  so  complicated  that  we 
were  not  prepared  to  submit  a  study  of  them  to  this  committee. 

Statistical  analysis  of  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel:  The  fore- 
going conclusions  as  to  the  elasticity  of  demand  were  tested  by  a 
separate  statistical  analysis  of  anrual  sciies  of  relevant  economic  data 


13594  CONCEKTKATION  OF  ECONOJMIC  POWEii 

from  1919  to  1938.  Production,  shipments  and  bookings  were  res- 
pectively correlated  with  the  factors  deemed  to  exert  a  significant 
influence  on  the  quantity  of  steel  demanded.     These  factors  were: 

(1)  The  price  of  steel. 

(2)  Industrial  production. 

(3)  Consumers'  income. 

(4)  Industrial  profits. 

(5)  A  time-trend  variable. 

From  four  such  correlations  involving  difl"erent  combinations  of 
these  factors,  it  was  found  that  a  1  percent  decrease  in  the  price  of 
steel  (other  factors  remaining  the  same)  would  induce  less  than  a  1 
percent  increase  hi  steel  sales.  Subsequent  calculations  in  which 
mill  net  yield?  on  shipments  of  steel,  not  available  at  the  time  of  the 
original  study,  were  used  in  lieu  of  published  prices,  confirmed  these 
results.  Although  subject'  to  considerable  error,  the  best  estimate 
of  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  indicated  by  this  analysis  is 
thought  to  be  approximately  0.3  or  0.4. 

These  findings  confirm  our  other  estimates  based  on  the  study  of 
the  demand  for  steel  b^^  consuming  industries,  and  indicate  that 
changes  in  the  level  of  steel  prices  cause  smaller  percentage  changes 
in  the  opposite  direct'ion  in  the  qu*'ntity  of  ;->tcei  sold. 

Mr.  O'CoNNELL.  May  I  nsk  u  question?  Why  did  you  use  the 
mill  net  yield  instead  of  anotlicr  basis  for  determining? 

Dr.  Yntema.  In  relating  shipments  to  price,  the  appropriate  price 
measure  to  use  is  the  price  obtained  on  the  shipment,  and  the  mill  net 
yields  constitute  that  particuhit  price. 

Mr.  O'CoNNELL.  Well,  tl;e  mill  net  yield  does  not  represent  :.he 
cost  to  the  purchaser  oi  steel,  does  it? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  but  the  mill  net  yield  fluctuates  in  the  cych  in 
very  close  correspondence  to  the  price  paid  by  the  customer.  If  'ou 
had  a  price  series  of  the  actual  average  prices  i^aid  by  the  buyers  of 
steel,  and  then  had  a  price  series  of  mill  net  yields,  the  percentage 
changes  in  both  series  would  be  almost  identical. 

Mr  O'CoNNELL.  You  mean  there  would  be  a  closer  correlation 
than  there  would  be  to  make  the  comparison  with  the  published  prices? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  there  are  two  points  that  I  am  making  here. 
One  is  that  if  you  are  studying  the  relation  of  shipments  to  some  price, 
then  it  must  be  the  price  paid  for  those  shipments.  The  second  point 
that  I  am  making  is  that  because  we  did  not  have  the  actual  prices 
paid  by  customers,  since  the  data  were  not  available  hi  convenient 
form,  we  used  a  series  which  paralleled  that  very  closely,  namely,  the 
average  mill  net  yield.  If  you  plotted  those  two  series,  you  would 
see  that  the  relative  fluctuations  in  them  were  almost  identical.  We 
do  not  have  the  two  series,  but  the  evidence  which  will  come  out  in  a 
later  discussion,  I  think,  will  indicate  this  beyond  any  reasonable 
doubt. 

m  the  j)eriod  covered  by  the  analysis,  changes  in  the  level  of  steel 
prices  were  a  comparatively  minor  influence  in  determining  changes 
in  the  volume  of  steel  sales.  Even  if  fiuctuations  in  steel  prices  had 
been  considerably  greatei*  than  they  wore,  ne\ertheles-;  other  factors 
aflecting  the  demand  for  steel,  such  as  consvuners'  income,  industrial 
profits,  and  general  business  activity,  were  found  to  bo  of  such  cou- 
trollmg  importance  that  they  would  still  h;ive  had  far  greater  weight 
than  changes  in  steel  prices. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  EXX>NOMIC  POWER  13595 

Relation  of  cost  to  volume  of  output:  Our  second  problem  was  to 
determine  how  costs  varied  with  output.  To  accomplish  this,  a 
study  was  made  of  the.  relation  between  cost  and  volume  for  the 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  during  the  period  from 
1927  to  1938.  In  computing  cost,  intercompany  items  were  excluded, 
as  were  Federal  income  taxes  and  costs  connected  with  extraneous 
nonoperating  transactions.  Since  the  purpose  of  the  analysis  was  to 
ascertain  the  changes  in  costs  which  would  result  from  changes  in 
volume  of  production,  the  effects  of  other  factors  had  to  be  excluded. 
This  necessitated  the  adjustment  of  the  cost  figures  for  each  of  the 
years  to  the  levels  of  material  prices,  wages,  interest,  and  tax  rates,  and 
pension  paympnts  prevailing  in  1938,  and  also  an  adjustment  for 
increases  in  efficiency  which  took  place  during  this  period.  Having 
removed  the  effects  of  changes  resulting  from  these  factors,  the  ad- 
justed costs  could  then  properly  be  related  to  volume  of  output. 

Because  of  variation  in  the  proportions  of  low  and  high  cost  prod- 
ucts, the  simple  aggregate  tonnage  of  these  products  was  not  a 
satisfactory  measure  of  output  for  our  purpose.  To  eliminate  the 
effect  of  these  variations  in  the  product  mix,  proper  weights  were 
assigned 'to  low  and  high  cost  products  and  an  annual  weighted  total 
of  products  shipped  was  thus  obtained.* 

When  the  average  relationship  of  adjusted  total  cost  to  weighted 
volume  was  obtained,  it  showed  that  within  a  range  of  operation 
from  18  percent  to  90  percent  of  ingot  capacity,  the  total  costs  of  the 
corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  under  1938  conditions  amounted  to 
$55.73  per  weighted  ton  plus  $182,100,000. 

It  should  be  noted  here  that  while  the  costs  mentioned  are  exclusive 
of  all  nonoperating  income  and  expense,  they  cover  all  operations  of 
the  Corporation  and,  hence,  do  not  represent  merely  the  cost  of  pro- 
ducing steel.  Furthermore,  even  weighted  tonnages  shipped  do  not 
reflect  the  full  volume  of  business,  since  some  goods  and  services  are 
sold  by  the  Corporation  which  are  not  measured  in  tons.  Nevertheless 
other  operations  rise  and  fall  with  increases  and  decreases  in  shipments 
of  products  to  a  sufficient  extent  that  the  total  costs  maintain  approxi- 
mately the  relationship  to  shipments  just  described.  Since  in  1938, 
89  percent  of  the  total  revenues  came  from  the  sale  of  steel,  presum- 
ably about  89  percent  of  the  above  costs  represent  costs  directly 
related  to  steel  production, 

Mr.  Reynders.  May  I  ask  a  question?  In  other  words,  when 
you  arrive  at  this  price,  you  include  such  items  as  fabricated  steel, 
going  into  buildings  and  ships? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes.  We  have  included  all  the  steel  products,  all 
the  hot  rolled  products,  shipped  by  the  Steel  Corporation  as  such. 

Mr.  Reynders.  But  only  the  rolled  products?  ' 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  should  like  to  correct  that  statement.  This  includes 
all  the  products  sold  in  the  form  they  are  sold  by  the  Steel  Corporation 
subsidiaries,  whatever  form  that  may  be. 

^  •.  Reynders.  Then  you  Lssign,  for  instance,  to  a  fabricated  steel 
a  liigher  relative  tonnage  rate. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes; -that  is  correct. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  In  that  range  from  18  percent  to  90  percent,  is 
this  the  cost,  $55.73,  or  would  it  vary  between  that  range? 

'  To  obtain  as  large  a 'coverage  as  possible,  this  weighted  total  included  also  products  other  than  steel  sold 
on  a  tonnage  basis  by  tne  Corporation  subsidiaries,  weighted  in  a  similar  manner. 

124491— 41— pt.  26 2 


13596 


CONC5ENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Dr.  Yntema.  No,  sir;  the  cost  is  composed  of  two  parts,  as  I  shall 
show  in  a  few  minutes,  a  total  of  $182,100,000  plus  an  additional  cost 
that  varies  with  output,  of  $55.73  per  weighted  ton.  I  want  to  make 
clear  that  that  is  not  strictly  the  additional  cost  per  weighted  ton  of 
steel.  If  you  could  allocate  these  additional  costs  on  the  basis  of 
revenues  obtained  from  steel  and  other  products,  i.  e.,  if  you  multi- 
plied thenx  by  89  percent  you  would  have  a  rough  working  estimate 
of  the  additional  cost  of  steel  per  ton. 

This  $182,100,000  represents  the  portion  of  the  costs  imder  1938 
conditions  which  remained  the  same,  independent  of  variations  in 
production  within  the  above-stated  capacities — provided,  of  course, 
that  other  factors  affecting  costs  stayed  constant.  This  "fixed  cost" 
included  not  only  interest  and  pensions,  but  also  the  portions  of  all 
other  costs  which  did  not  vary  with  output.  The  $55.73  per  weighted 
ton  represents  the  additional  cost  of  all  operations  per  additional  ton 
of  product.  This  additional  cost  per  ton  remains  constant  through- 
out the  range  of  operations  covered  by  the  data.  The  average  cost 
per  ton,- of  course,  decreases  as  volume  rises. 

^The  elements  coniposing  these  additional  and  fixed  costs  follow  in 
table  1 : 


Table  1. — Elements  of  total  costs,  1938  conditions,  United  States  Steel  Corporation 
and  subsidiaries 


Additional 

cost  for 

Cost  that 

each  addi- 

Item 

does  not 

tional 

vary  with 

weighted 

production 

ton  of 
product 
shipped 

Interest _ 

$8, 300, 000- 
7,  700,  000 
24,  200, 000 

0 

$1.43 

Payroll _. -.... 

62,100,000- 
2,500,000 

29.10 

Social  Security  taxes 

1.16 

47,  800,  000 

21.67 

Total  cash  costs 

152,600,000 

53.36 

29.500,000 

2.37 

Total  costs  -- 

182,100,000 

55  73 

Acting  Chairman  King.  It  may  be  included  in  your  testimony. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  should  like  to  point  out  one  or  two  characteristics 
of  this  table.  In  the  first  place,  that  of  the  $55.73  additional  cost 
per  weighted  ton  of  products  shipped.  The  additional  pay  roll  ac- 
counts for  $29  and  the  additional  other  cash  expenses,  made  up 
largely  of  materials  and  services  purchased  from  others,  account  for 
$21.  The  depreciation  and  depletion  is  a  relatively  small  item  of 
the  total. 

Of  the  total  costs,  $53.36  of  the  additional  costs  and  $152,600,000 
of  the  fixed  costs  are  cash  outlays,  and  the  respective  remainders 
consist  of  depreciation  and  depletion. 

I  might  interpolate  there  with  one  comment,  that  even  in  the  case 
of  depreciation  and  depletion  you  can't  avoid  entirely  some  of  the 
expenditures  necessary  for  replacements  and  additions  to  equipment 
during  depression.  Those  are  costs  which  in  the  long  run  also  must 
be  met  in  cash. 


GONCENTRATIOISt  Oli'  EOONOMIC  POWER  13597 

Mr.  HiNRiCHs.  May  I  ask  one  question  in  this  connection?  In 
these  costs  that  do  not  vary  with  production  you  show  a  total  of 
$62,100,000  for  labor. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes,  sir. 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  And  you  then  show  variable  pay-roll  costs  of  $29.10 
a  ton. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes. 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  For  additional  labor  per  ton  for  whatever  volume  of 
production  there  may  be.  That  indicates  an  absolutely  linear 
relationship  as  far  as  labor  costs  are  concerned,  yet  fixity  in  the 
bottom  end,  perfect  variability  within  the  range  of  18  to  90  percent 
of  capacity  production.  Have  you  tested  out  other  types  of  relation- 
ship as  well  as  the  straight  linear  relationship?  Are  you  convinced 
on  the  basis  of  numerous  other  tests  that  that  relationship  is  abso- 
lutely linear,  because  that  is  a  difiFerent  concept  than  I  think  the  steel 
industry  itself  has  had  in  the  past. 

Dr.  Yntema.  In  "Exhibit  No.  1416,"  p.  28,^  there  is  a  chart  which 
mdicates  the  relation  of  pay  rolls  to  millions  of  weighted  tons  of  all 
tonnage  products  shipped.  The  dots  cluster  very  close  to  a  straight 
line. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  I  am  sorry,  my  memory  for  numbers  isn't  good. 

Dr.  Yntema.  It  is  "Exhibit  No.  1416,"  entitled  "An  Analysis  -of 
Steel  Prices  Volmne  and  Costs." 

Mr.  HiNRiCHs.  Summary? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No,  the  larger  pamphlet. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  Page  28,.  you  say?  ^ 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes,  sir. 

Dr.  Kreps.  We  shall  have  something  to  say  about  that  linear  rela- 
tionship when  Dr.  Louis  Bean  takes  the  stand. 

Mr.  HiNRicHs.  My  question  was  essentially  whether  you  had  tried 
other  types  of  relationship  as  well  and  concluded  that  this  was  the  most 
significant. 

Dr.  Yntema.  No,  we  hayen't  tried  other  types  of  relationship. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  This  is  based  on  the  inspection 

Dr.  Yntema  (interposing).  It  is  based  on  inspection.  I  should  be 
reasonably  certain,  however,  that  with  inspection  you  wouldn't  obtam 
a  better  fit  from  some  other  function.  That  is  supported  by  oth.er  stud- 
ies we  have  made.  We  have  analyzed  the  relationship  of  man-hours  to 
output  by  months  and  also  by  subdivisions  of  the  Corporation,  and  in 
most  cases  we  get  very  nearly  a  straight-line  relationship,  although  in 
some  instances,  surprisingly  enough,  the  tendency  is  for  the  line  not 
to  rise  throughout  at  a  constant  rate  but,  at  the  higher  rates  of  ppera- 
tion,  to  fail  to  rise  at  the  same  rate  as  it  does  in  the  lower  range  of  the 
curve.  I  should  say,  however,  that  you  get  a  vdry  good  description 
of  the  behavior  of  labor  costs  in  relation  to  output — when  you  have 
adjusted  for  differences  of  the  average  hourly  earnings  at  different 
points — by  fitting  a  straight  line  to  the  data. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Proceed. 

EFFECTS    OF    PRICE    REDUCTIONS 

Dr.  Yntema.  From  the  relationship  between  costs  and  volume  it 
is  possible  to  determine  the  increa-se  in  volume  necessary  to  compen- 

>  Appendix,  p.  14053. 


13598  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

sate  for  a  given  price  reduction.  Although  our  estimates  of  the 
elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  are  less  than  1,  it  will  be  assumed  in 
the  following  calculations  that  a  given  percentage  reduction  in  price 
will  cause  an  equal  relative  increase  in  the  volume  of  steel  sold,  so  that 
the  dollar  amount  of  sales  will  remain  the  same.  In  other  words,  the 
elasticity  of  demand  will  be  assumed  equal  to  1. 

The.  sales  and  revenues  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsid- 
iaries ill  1938  amounted  to  $77.66  per  weighted  ton  of  products  shipped. 
Of  this  amount  $71.86  represented  the  amount  received  from  the  sale 
of  steel  and  other  products,  and  $5.80  represented  income  from 
transportation  and  miscellaneous  operations. 

On  the  assumption  of  unitary  elasticity  of  demand  and  no  increase 
in  transportation  and  miscellaneous  operating  revenues,  a  10  percent 
decrease  from  the  average  price  level  in  1938  would  require  an  increase 
of'48.8  percent  in  volume  of  shipments  to  avoid  loss  from  price  reduc- 
tion. But  the  maximum  increase  in  volume  to  be  expected  from  the 
price  reduction,  on  the  assumption  made,  is  only  1 1  percent.  Thus  it 
is  clear  that  a  price  decrease  would  induce  only  a  small  proportion  of 
the  tonnage  increase  which  would  be  necessary  to  compensate  for  it. 

In  table  2  this  relationship  is  shown  for  price  reductions  ranging  from 
1  to  20  percent, 

I  should  like  to  insert  table  2  in  the  record  and  defer  discussion  until 
a  later  time  when  I  shall  show  a  chart  which  perhaps  will  bring  out 
more  clearly  the  significance  of  this  material. 

Table  2. — Percentage  increases  in  volume  needed  to  offset  various  "percentage  reduc- 
tions from  average  19S8  prices  and  effect  of  price  reductions  on  losses — United 
States  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Percentage 

Estimated 

Percent- 
age re- 
duction 
in  price 

incre^e  in 
volume 

needed  to 

compensate 

for  price 

reduction 

Percentage 
increase, 
assuming 

elasticity  of 

1 

Estimated 

additional 

loss,  assuming 

elasticity  of  1 

additional 

loss,  if  no 

increase  in 

volume 

resulted  from 

price  reduction 

1 

3.3? 

1.0 

$3,900,000 

$5,600,000 

2 

7.01 

2.0 

7,900.000 

11,200,000 

10.91 

3.1 

12.000,000 

16.800,000 

U.OO 

4.2 

16, 200, 000 

22,400,000 

IQ.fiO 

5.3 

20,500,000 

28,000.000 

24.48 

6.4 

24.900,000 

33,  600, 000 

29.77 

7.5 

2^,300,000 

39,  200, 000 

35.  54 

8.7 

33,900,000 

44,800,000 

41.83 

9.9 

38,  500,  oon 

50. 400, 000 

10 

48.75 

11.1 

43, 300,  000 

56,  100, 000 

11 

56.38 

12.4 

48, 100, 000 

61,700,000 

12 

64.82 

13.6 

53,  100, 000 

67,  300,  000 

13 

74.24 

14.9 

58,  200,  000 

72,900.000 

U 

84.78 

16.3 

63, 400, 000 

78.  500, 000 

15 

96.70 

17.7 

08,  700,  000 

84.100,000 

20 

190.  26 

25.0 

97,  400,  0(X) 

112,100,000 

In  1938  the  subsidiaries  of  thj  United  States  Steel  Corporation 
shipped  7,800,000  weighted  tons,  while  in  1937  they  shipped 
13,200,000  tons.  To  bring  the  1938  weighted  tonnage  up  to  the  1937 
level,  a  69.23  percent  increase  would  have  been  necessary.  On  the 
assumption  of  a  unitary  elasticity  of  demand,  this  would  have  required 
a  price  decrease  of  40.9  percent.  After  such  a  price  reduction,  revenue 
per  ^veighted  ton  would  have  been  $48.26,  or  $5.10  less  than  the 
additional  cost  per  ton  of  products  shipped.  On  the  assumption 
(contrary  to  our  previous  findings)  that  the  price  reduction  of  40  9 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13599 

percent  would  have  been  sufficient  to  restore  the  1937  vohime,  13,- 
200,000  weighted  tons  would  have  been  sold.  The  Corporation  and 
its  subsidiaries  would  then  have  had  a  cash  loss  of  $152,600,000  out- 
of-pocket  fixed  costs  plus  a  further  loss  of  $5.10  per  ton,  or  a  total  cash 
loss  of  $219,920,000.  If  depreciation  and  depletion  of  assets  at  this 
rate  of  operations,  amounting  to  $60,784,000,  were  added  to  the  cash 
loss,  the  total  loss  would  have  been  $280,704,000.  In  1  year  this 
would  have  wiped  out  more  than  half  the  current  assets  of  the  Corpo- 
ration. 

The  1938  price  level  used  in  the  foregoing  calculations  is  the  average 
price  in  effect  both  before  and  after  the  June  1938  reduction  of  approxi- 
mately 10  percent  in  the  published  prices.  The  relationship  between 
annual  sales  and  revenues  and  annual  costs  at  various  levels  oi  pro- 
duction has  also  been  computed  on  the  basis  of  prices  prevailing  during 
the  second  half  of  1938.  At  this  lower  price  level  the  break-even 
point  (under  1938  cost  conditions,  without  any  allowance  for  di^ndends 
on  preferred  stock)  would  have  been  at  about  10,500,000  weighted 
tons,  which  is  equivalent  to  an  operating  rate  of  50  to  55  percent  of 
capacity.  A  10-percent  reduction  in  prices  from  this  level  would 
have  raised  the  break-even  point  to  about  90  percent  of  capacity. 
If  the  break-even  point  were  this  high,  the  Corporation  would  have 
to  operate  at  the  impossible  annual  rate  of  130  percent  of  capacity 
to  earn  a  return  before  income  taxes  of  only  5  percent  on  its  invest- 
ment in  tangible  assets. 

At  this  point,  if  it  please  the  committee,  I  should  like  to  show  this 
material  in  cha,rt  form.     I  think  it  may  be  somewhat  clearer. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Proceed. 

Dr.  Yntema.  This  is  chart  B-9  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409."^  It  is 
entitled  "Unadjusted  Costs  and  Volume  of  Business  Compared  With 
Estimated  Costs  for  Corresponding  Volumes  Under  1938  Conditions." 
For  the  time  being  I  should  like  to  neglect  this  dotted  line,  we  have 
drawn  through  the  chart;  I  will  come  back  and  show  the  significance 
of  that  later  on. 

We  have  plotted  here  the  millions  of  dollars  of  costs,  the  actual 
unadjusted  costs," neglecting,  however,  intercompany  items  and  non- 
operating  transactions  which  are  extraneous  to  the  production  process 
of  the  Corporation.  We  have  plotted  here  the  millions  of  weighted 
tons  of  all  tonnage  products  shipped;  that  is,  weighting  the  lower-cost 
products  and  the  higher-cost  products  in  such  a  way  as  to  obtain  as 
satisfactory  an  index  of  volume  of  production  as  possible. 

These  dots  represent  the  costs  and  the  volume  of  production  in  the 
respective  years.  For  example,  in  1929  the  cost  of  production  was 
represented  by  the  height  at  this  point  above  the  base  line,  and  the 
distance  from  the  left-hand  side  of  the  chart  over  to  the  point  repre- 
sents the  tons  of  products  shipped. 

These  are  the  data  with  which  we  began  our  cost  analysis.  They 
are  the  actual  unadjusted  costs  and  the  weighted  tonnages  of  products 
shipped.  You  can  see  that  even  without  any  adjustment  they  are 
distributed  roughly  along  o,  straight  line. 

I  should  like  to  show  now,  by  another  chart,  the  effect  of  our  adjust- 
ments upon  these  points. 

Dr.  Kreps.  What  number  is  this  next  chart? 

» Appendix,  p.  13789. 


13600  CONOBNTRATION  OP  EJOONOMIC  POWER 

Dr.  Yntema.  This  is  No.  B-1  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409,"  '  entitled 
"Relationship  Between  Total  Costs  of  Operation  and  Volume  of 
Business — 1938  Conditions."  Along  the  horizontal  base  line  we  are 
still  plotting  the  millions  of-  weighted  tons  of  all  tonnage  products 
shipped.  There  has  been  no  adjustment  in  that  for  each  of  the  years, 
but  we  have  in  each  year  adjusted  these  total  costs  as  I  have  described 
in  the  statement  just  subm.itted  to  the  committee.  In  each  case  we 
have  taken  the  components  of  cost,  the  pay  rolls,  the  taxes,  and  other 
costs,  and  adjusted  them  to  the  wage  rate,  tax,  and  material  price 
conditions  existing  in  1938  insofar  as  those  adjustments  were  possible. 
We  don't  claim  perfection  for  such  adjustments.  There  are  many 
obstacles  in  the  way  of  achieving  perfection,  but  we  think  these 
represent  reasonably  satisfactory  adjustments.  I  understand  there 
will  be  som.e  discussion  of  Ihis  question  later  before  the  committee. 
There  may  be  more  elaboration  of  these  adjustments  at  that  time. 

Even  a  casual  inspection  of  the  chart  will  show  that  these  points 
lie  very  closely  upon  a  straight  line,  and  we  have  therefore  fitted  such 
a  line  to  these  observations.  This  line  purports  to  show,  then,  how 
the  total  costs  of  the  Steel  Corporation  would  vary  with  variation  in 
volume,  removing,  however,  the  effects  of  changes  in  wage  rates, 
material  prices,  tax  rates;  it  shows  how  total  costs  would  respond  to 
changes  in  one  factor  alone,  changes  in  volume. 

We  don't  particularly  want  to  call  attention  to  the  extrapolation 
of  this  line  beyond  the  range  of  the  data.  We  are  not  interested  in 
that.  Extrapolating  the  line  does  give,  however,  a  convenient 
method  of  describing  how  the ,  costs  behave.  This  amount  of 
$182,100,000  we  have  determined  as  fixed  cost.  It  represents  in  a 
sense  the  amount  of  cost  which  does  not  vary  with  output.  The  total 
costs  rise  by  a  constant  amount  per  ton  as  the  volume  increases. 
That  increase  in  total  costs,  per  ton  increase  in  volume,  is  the  addi- 
tional cost,  $55.73,  which  I  have  described  in  the  statement  just 
read  to  you. 

This  next  chart  is  No.  B-2  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409."  ^  It  is  entitled 
"Composition  of  Total  Costs  of  Operation  in  Relation  to  Volume  of 
Business."  It  shows  total  costs  in  relation  to  output,  exactly  the 
same  line  that  was  just  presented  to  you  in  chart  B-1.  We  have 
taken  the  line  of  total  costs  from  chart  B-1  and  placed  it  here.  Then 
we  made  an  analysis  of  the  behavior  of  the  individual  components 
of  cost;  we  took  the  components  of  the  total  cost  and  studied  how  they 
were  related  to  volume.  This  chart  gives  the  result  of  those  studies. 
They  are.  described  in  somewhat  greater  detail  in  "Exhibit  No.  1416" 
entitled  "Analysis  of  Steel  Prices,  Volume  and  Costs." 

CASH  COSTS 

Dr.  Yntema.  There  are  two  characteristics  of  this  chart  which 
I  think  are  intercbting.  •  One  of  them  is  the  relatively  small  proportion 
of  noncash  outlays.  The  goods  and  services  pm-chased  from  others 
must  be  paid  for  in  cash  from  year  to  year.  Social  Security  taxes 
must  be  paid  for  in  cash  from  year  to  year.  The  pay  rell  must  be 
paid  for  in  cash  from  year  to  year.  The  depreciation  and  depletion 
to  some  extent,  to  a  very  considerable  extent,  may  be  deferred,  but 

1  Appendix,  p.  13773. 
•  Appendix,  pi  13776. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13601 

even  that  cannot  be  completely  deferred  in  depression;  what  I  mean 
is  that  there  is  even  in  depression  necessity  for  making  some  expendi- 
tm-e  for  replacement  of  equipment.  The  taxes  other  than  Federal 
income  and  Social  Secm-ity  taxes  must  be  met  in  cash  from  year  to 
year.  You  notice,  therefore,  that  of  the  total  costs,  the  total  variable 
costs,  so-called,  practically  all  of  them  are  cash  outlays;  only  a  very 
small  proportion  represents  noncash  outlays.  Of  the  so-called  costs 
which  we  have  termed  "fixed  costs"  the  goods  and  services  purchased 
from  others  must  be  paid  for  in  cash;  the  Social  Security  taxes  must  be 
paid  in  cash;  the  pay  roU  of  course  must  be  met  by  cash  expenditure; 
the  depreciation  and  depletion  does  not  represent  entirely  immediate 
cash  outlays.  The  taxes  other  than  Federal  income  and  Social 
Security  taxes  must  be  met  in  cash,  and  pensions,  and  interest  of 
course  represent  cash  payments. 

In  summary,  therefore,  the  proportion  of  noncash  overhead  is 
indeed  very  small.  You  will  notice,  furthermore,  that  we  have  not 
included  in  this  chart  any  provision  for  dividends  or  profits. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Does  the  item  of  goods  and  services  purchased 
from  others  include  only  raw  materials  used  in  the  manufacture  and 
production  of  steel? 

Dr.  Yntema.  It  includes  raw  materials  purchased  from  others. 
Mr.  Wooden.  For  use  only  in  the  manufacture  of  steel? 
Dr.  Yntema.  For  use  by  the  Steel  Corporation  in  all  its  operations. 
We  have  tried  to  bring  together  all  operations  in  this  picture.  The 
reason  for  doing  that  is  not  that  we  did  not  want  to  analyze  the 
components,  but  that  any  analysis  of  the  component  operations  would 
involve  questions  of  accounting  allocation  which  of  necessity  would  be 
arbitrary. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Do  you  have  any  break-down  between  the  cost  of 
goods  the  cost  of  services  purchased  from  others? 

Dr.  Yntema.  It  wasn't  possible  for  us  to  obtain  that  break-down 
without  a  tremendous  amount  of  work.  If  it  had  been  available  we 
would  have  used  it,  but  we  found  it  was  impossible  to  get  that  in- 
formation because  of  the  particular  way  in  which  the  records  of  the 
Corporation  were  kept,  each  subsidiary  corporation's  records  being 
kept  as  a  separate  entity. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  When  you  speak  of  pay  roll  you  are  referring  to 
all  payments  for  services,  including  your  salaried  workers,  payments 
to  ofiicials  as  well  as  wage  earners? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes,  sir;  but  not  for  all  services,  it  doesn't  include 
some  types  of  professional  service  obtained  from  others,  but  it  includes 
all  the  salaried  pay  roll  to  the  corporation  employees. 

Mr.  Reynders.  They  are  in  that  lower  range  of  salaried  pay  roll 
shown  on  this  chart,  aren't  they? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  can't  tell  you  what  the  distribution  is.  A  good 
deal  of  the  salaried  employees  I  think  wou'd  appear  in  this  pay  roll 
included  among  "fixed  costs"  at  the  bottom  of  the  chart,  but  even 
there  it  may  not  be  entirely  true.  I  just  can't  tell  you  the  extent  to 
which  this  item  is  composed  of  wage  earners  and  the  extent  to  which 
it  is  composed  of  salaried  workers. 

Mr.  Reynders.  The  straight-line  characteristic  of  your  labor  is  a 
fortuitous  circumstance,  isn't  it,  because  the  higher  operating  rate 
you  have,  the  higher  are  the  rates  of  labor. 


13602       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  we  have  eliminated  the  effects  of  differences  of 
average  hourly  earnings  for  all  employees.  We  found  by  study  that 
the  average  hourly  earnings  of  all  employees,  wage  earners  and  others, 
are  approximately  the  same,  independent  of  output,  so  long  as  there 
are  not  wage  rate  changes.  We  have  a  chart  here  which  we  will  be 
glad  to  put  in  evidence  if  you  would  like  to  see  it,  showing  that  parti- 
cular point.  I  think  later  on  in  the  discussion  we  should  like  to  pre- 
sent it  to  the  committee. 

In  this  next  chart.  No.  B-3,  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409,"  ^  entitled  "Rela- 
tionship Between  Sales  and  Costs — Effect  of  Reduction  from  Average 
1938  Prices,"  again  we  have  taken  this  line  representing  total  costs 
determined  in  the  earlier  chart,  No.  B-1,  and  we  have  superimposed 
upon  this  chart  two  other  lines,  one — the  light  double  line — represent- 
ing total  sales  and  revenues  at  1938  average  prices.  This  light  double 
line  represents  what  average  sales  and  revenues  at  the  various  volumes 
would  be  under  1938  prices.  In  other  words,  the  height  of  this  line 
at  any  giv^n  point  of  volume  represents  what  the  total  sales  and  reve- 
nues would  have  been  at  1938  prices  if  this  volume  had  been  sold. 

The  point  at  which  the  total  sales  and  revenues  are  equal  to  the 
total  costs,  sometimes  called  the  break-even  point,  appears  in  this 
chart  at  approximately  8,300,000  weighted  tons  of  all  tonnage  prod- 
ucts shipped,  on  the  basis  of  average  1938  prices.  If  the  price  had 
been  reduced,  if  the  1938  average  prices'  had  been  10  percent  lower, 
the  sales  and  revenues  line  would  have  been  represented  by  this  heavy 
broken  line  on  this  chart.  You  see  that  for  any  given  volume  of 
product  the  height  of  this  line  is  IQ  percent  less  than  that  of  the  light 
double  line  above  it  on  this  chart. 

The  break-even  point  in  that  latter  case  would  have  come  at  ap- 
proximately 12,500,000  tons  of  aU  tonnage  products  shipped,  or 
roughly  the  break-even  point  would  have  been  in  the  neighborhood 
of  70  percent  of  capacity.  This  shows  the  effect  of  a  10-percent  reduc- 
tion from  the  1938  average  price  level  upon  the  break-even  point. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  You  just  said  70  percent;  in  your  earlier  testimony, 
if,  I  remember  correctly,  you  said  a  10-percent  reduction  in  prices 
would  have  raised  the  break-even  point  to  about  90  percent  of  ca- 
pacity. 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  that  applies  to  the  level  of  prices  prevailing  in 
the  second  half  of  1938,  and  I  will  show  in  just  a  moment  a  chart 
corresponding  to  that  testimony. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Is  it  a  composite  base  price  or  a  composite  mill-net 
yield  that  you  have  used  there? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  the  composite  of  actual  receipts. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Mill-net  yield? 

Dr.  Yntema.  This  is  mill-net  yields  for  aU  steel  products  and  net 
vields  to  the  Corporation  from  all  other  nonsteel  products  as  well. 

This  next  chart  is  No.  B-4  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409."  =^  It  is  entitled 
"Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Various  Decreases 
in  1938  Prices  Compared  to  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume." 

You  will  remember  in  the  statements  which  I  made  a  few  minutes 
ago  that  WG  assumed  in  our  calculations  an  elasticity  of  1  for  demand 
for  steel,  although  we  thought  the  elasticity  was  considerably  lower 
than  that.     We  have  plotted  along  the  base  line  the  percentage  de- 

•  Appendix,  p.  13777. 
'  Appendix,  p.  13779. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13603 

creases  from  the  average  1938  prices,  and  this  black  line  labeled  "Prob- 
able Resulting  Increases  in  Volume"  shows  what  the  volume  increase 
would  have  been  if  the  elasticity  of  demand  were  unity. 

The  height  of  the  bars  in  the  chart  shows  what  the  increase  in 
volume  would  have  had  to  be  if  the  price  decrease  had  not  brought  a 
financial  loss  to  the  corporation.  You  can  see  very  readily  that  in 
all  cases  the  needed  increase  in  volume  required  to  offset  the  decrease 
in  price  was  far  greater  than  any  increase  in  volume  which  could  reason- 
ably be  expected  to  eventuate  from  the  price  reduction. 

This  next  chart  is  numbered  B-5  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409."  It  is 
entitled  "Estimated  Additions  to  1938  Deficit.  How  Deficit  Would 
Have  Increased  if  Prices  Had  Been  Reduced  and  Volume  Had 
Increased  to  Same  Relative  Extent."  In  this  chart  we  have  plotted 
along  the  base  line  various  percentage  reductions  in  the  1938  average 
price.  The  black  part  of  the  bar  in  each  case  represents  what  the  1 938 
deficit  of  the  Steel  Corporation  actually  was.  The  dotted  part  of  the 
bar  above  the  black  portion  represents  the  addition  to  the  deficit  if 
prices  had  been  reduced  as  indicated  by  these  respective  percentages 
on  the  base  line.  Thus,  for  example,  if  there  had  been  a  10  percent 
reduction  in  price  the  additional  deficit  would  have  been  indicated  by 
the  large  dotted  portion  of  the  bar  above  the  lower  black  portion  over 
the  figure  10  on  the  base  line. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Would  you  carefully  state  for  the  committee  what  the 
assumption  is  upon  which  you  base  these  estimates? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes.  We  have  assumed,  first,  an  elasticity  of 
demand  of  one  for  steel. 

Dr.  Keeps.  By  demand  you  mean  market  demand  rather  than 
demand  in  what  is  called  the  schedule  sense? 

Dr.  Yntema.  We  use  elasticity»in  this  sense,  that  if  the  price  were 
reduced  1  percent  there  would  be  a  1  percent  increase  in  quantity  of 
steel  which  would  be  bought. 

Dr.  Keeps.  You  mean  you  are,  therefore,  allowing  for  no  effect  in 
the  reduction  of  the  price  of  steel  upon  general  business  activity,  con- 
sumer income,  and  industrial  profits. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes.  We  are  neglecting  for  the  time  any  such  indirect 
effects;  it  seems  to  me  beyond  possible  doubt  that  the  indirect  effects 
increasing  the  possible  elasticity  would  be  far  less  than  the  error  we 
have  made  by  assuming  as  high  an  elasticity  as  one.  I  state  that 
merely  as  my  own  personal  opinion,  that  we  have  erred  on  the  upper 
side.  Even  if  we  took  the  definition  which  you  have  suggested  as  an 
alternative  I  think  the  elasticity  still  would  not  be  greater  than  one. 

Dr.  Keeps.  This  does  not  depend  so  much  upon  the  elasticity  of 
.  demand  as  upon  the  nature  of  yoiir  cost  curve,  does  it  not? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  should  say  that  it  depended  upon  both,  that  if  you 
made  large  changes  in  either  one  you  would  get  somewhat  different 
results,  but  if  you  made  moderate  changes  in  the  cost  function  or 
moderate  changes  in  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel,  either  one,  you 
would  still  get  substantially  the  same  order  of  results. 

Dr.  Keeps.  You  agree  that  general  business  activity,  consumer 
income,  and  industrial  profits  affect  the  volume  of  steel  sold,  do  you 
not? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Ob,  that  is  correct,  they  are  much  more  important 
than  price. 


13604       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  do  not  mean  to  say  that  the  volume  of  steel 
sold,  the  amount  of  employment  in.  the  steel  industry,  steel  being 
roughly  $1  out  of  14,  in  the  economy,  has  no  effect  upon  industrial 
activity,  upon  consumer  income,  and  upon  industrial  profits? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  I  would  never  want  to  be  quoted  to  that  effect — 
that  the  amount  of  steel  sold  has  no  effect. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Yet  in  your  charts  you  have  made  no  such  allowance, 
have  you? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Let  me  make  clear  what  we  have  in  the  charts.  We 
have  assumed  with  reference  to  the  elasticity  of  demand  a  figure  which 
we  think  is  high,  perhaps  twice  or  three  times  as  high  as  we  believe  to 
be  the  best  estimate.  We  have  tried  to  be  conservative  in  that 
respect.  We  would  recognize  that  if  you  allow  for  the  secondary- 
repercussions  there  would  be  perhaps  some  increase  in  that  elasticity. 
I  personally  regard  those  effects  as  much  smaller  than  the  margin  of 
error  which  we  have  introduced  by  assuming  an  elasticity  of  1  instead 
of  0.3  or  0.4. 

Dr.  Kreps.  That  is  your  own  personal  estimate.  You  have  made 
no  calculations? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  I  don't  see  how  it  would  be  possible  to  make 
satisfactory  calculations  on  that  point. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  have  made  no  endeavor  to  show  to  what  extent 
the  activity  in  the  steel  industry  and  the  leadership  furnished  by 
steel  executives  and  by  steel  price  policies  tends  to  influence  if  not 
affect  and  determine  general  industrial  activity  and  the  general  level 
of  industrial  prices? 

Dr.  Yntema.  We  are  carrying  on  research,  not  in  the  Steel  Corpora- 
tion but  in  the  Cowles  Commission  at  the  University  of  Chicago,  on 
the  demand  for  steel,  and  if  you  or  anyone  else  has  any  other  sugges- 
tions as  to  how  to  proceed  in  such  an  investigation  we  shall  be  more 
than  delighted  to  receive  them. 

Dr.  Kreps.  We  have  some  suggestions  in  that  regard. 

I  want  merely  to  make  clear  for  the  record  that  the  assumption 
upon  which  these  charts  are  based  is  contrary  to  economic  fact. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  Dr.  Yntema,  I  have  been  very  much  impressed 
with  your  logic,  but  I  have  one  question  I  want  to  ask.  Why  does 
the  Steel  Corporation  ever  reduce  prices  then,  since  it  seems  to  be  a 
ruinous  policy?  I  mean  they  are  going  to  sell  the  same  amount  of 
steel  for  less  revenue.     That  doesn't  seem  to  make  sense. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  don't  like  to  get  into  a  long  discussion.  I  think 
the  answer  is  competition. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  If  there  were  none? 

Dr.  Yntema.  If  there  were  no  competition  in  the  steel  industry  the 
prices  would  certainly  be  much  higher  than  they  are  and  have  been 
In  short,  I  think  it  is  due  to  competition  in  the  steel  industry. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  Assuming  there  was  no  competition,  is  there  any 
way  you  can  explain  it  except  there  is  elasticity  to  the  demand  for 
steel?  Suppose  we  settle  that,  then  how  could  you  explain  a  reduction 
in  the  price  of  steel  except  on  the  condition  that  the  demand  for  steel 
was  elastic? 

Dr.  Yntema.  If  there  were  no  competition — that  is  a  condition 
which  I  think  is  contrary  to  fact — in  the  steel  industry 

Mr.  Ballinger  (interposing).  Price  competition. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13605 

Dr.  Yntema.  No  price  competition  in  the  steel  industry,  no 
effective  price  competition  in  the  steel  industry?  I  think  you  could 
explain  these  facts  only  by  the  goodheartedness  of  the  steel  industry. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Is  it  not  a  fact  that  in  many  industries 
during  this  depression  and  even  at  other  times  there  have  been  losses, 
deficits,  which  have  been  made  too  often  by  invading  capital  and  im- 
pairing utimately  the  economic  structure  or  stability  of  the  corporation 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  didn't  get  one  part  of  the  question — by  doing  what 
to  capital? 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Invading  capital. 

Dr.  Yntema.  By  invading  capital? 

Acting  Chairman  King.  That  is  making  it  less  valuable. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Of  course,  it  is  true  that  if  an  industry  does  not  main- 
tain its  productive  facilities  at  a  level  with  current  technological 
advances,  consumers  suffer  thereby.  I  think  it  is  possible  to  name 
industries  of  that  sort.  I  am  no  expert  in  the  railroad  industry,  but 
I  think  the  railroads  have  suffered  so  severe  a  depression  that  that 
probably  has  been  true.  I  can't  offer  that  as  expert  opinion,  but 
only  as  a  lay  observer. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  From  your  studies  of  our  economic  and 
industrial  situation  have  you  discovered  that  many  industries  continue 
to  function  as  best  they  may,  even  though  they  are  sustaining  annually 
very  severe  losses? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  that  there  are  many  industries  which,  in  spite 
of  the  losses  they  sustain,  stUl  maintain  a  fairly  high  level  of  technical 
efficiency.  I  think  there  is  no  doubt  but  that  in  depression  technical 
advances  may  sometimes  be  slowed  up  due  to  the  fact  you  cite.  It  is 
hard  to  generalize  in  as  complicated  a  question  as  that.  I  doubt  if 
that  has  been  a  major  factor  retarding  technical  progress.  I  don't 
think  it  has  in  the  steel  industry. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  didn't  refer  particularly  so  much  to 
technical  progress,  but  merely  to  disposition  of  men  in  business 
whether  small  business  or  large  business,  whether  in  the  agricultural 
business,  the  production  of  agricultural  commodities,  sugar  for 
instance,  or  in  the  mining  industry  in  the  production  of  copper,  lead, 
zinc,  and  other  ores,  is  it  not  a  fact  that  in  many  of  those  cases  there 
have  been  losses  for  protracted  periods  and  yet  the  mines  couldn't 
afford  to  close  down,  the  agriculturists  couldn't  afford  not  to  plow  their 
fields,  they  had  to  raise  something,  and  they  have  met  their  losses 
with  a  good  deal  of  courage  and  sometimes  they  haven't  met  them 
and  have  gone  into  bankruptcy,  but  have  continued  oftentimes  for 
indefinite  periods,  hoping  that  the  clouds  would  be  dissipated  and 
the  sun  would  again  shine. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  that  there  are  many  stockholders  in  the 
steel  industry  and  many  managers  in  the  steel  industry  who  would 
have  a  sympathetic  response  to  that  suggestion. 

Dr.  Keeps.  And  laborers  you  would  add,  wouldn't  you? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yss;  quite  so. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  When  corporations  shut  down  or  close 
their  business  or  farmers  don't  produce,  when  mines  shut  down,  the 
laborers  suffer  of  course,  so  obviously  it  doesn't  need  any  explanation. 

Mr.  Feller.  Assuming  that  the  rate  of  operation  of  the  Corporation 
is  in  the  neighborhood  of  80  percent  today,  does  it  foUow  from  your 


13606  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

charts  that  if  the  Corporation  were  to  double  its  price  today  and  be 
content  with  a  rate  of  operation  of  40  percent  they  would  make  just  as 
much  money? 

If  you  take  half  the  production  at  twice  the  price  and  make  just  the 
same  profit? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  you  would  make  a  larger  profit.  If  you  ob- 
tained the  same  total  income  and  reduced  your  costs  you  would  make 
a  larger  profit  than  you  did  before. 

Mr.  Feller.  Your  costs  would  be  reduced? 

Dr.  Yntena.  Yes;  if  you  reduced  your  operations  from  80  to  40 
percent. 

Mr.  Feller.  On  your  calculation,  you  mean  the  average  cost  per 
ton  of  steel  would  go  down? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  the  average  cost  per  ton  of  steel  would  go  up. 

Mr.  Feller.  If  you  reduced  your  operation  to  40  percent? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  but  the  margin  would  be  so  much  greater  that 
the  total  profit  would  greatly  exceed  the  current  profit. 
*   Mr.  Feller.  Then  isn't  the  industry  very  foolish  in  attempting  to 
get  all  this  business?    Why  don't  they  go  after  less  business? 

Dr.  Yntema.  It  is  true  that  if  any  business  were  perfectly  free  to  set 
its  prices  anywhere  it  pleased,  most  businesses  would  set  their  prices 
higher  and  most  businesses  would  make  larger  profits,  but  that  is  not 
the  way  business  has  to  operate.  Most  business  today  is  competitive, 
and  the  limits  upon  the  prices  which  any  particular  business  can  set 
are  determined  by  competition.  It  is  not  possible  for  the  Steel  Cor- 
poration or  for  any  concern  in  the  steel  industry  to  set  its  prices  at 
any  level  that  it  pleases.  These  phenomena  would  reveal  that  fact 
if  they  were  approached  with  some  understanding  of  the  degree  of 
competition  which  does  exist  in  the  steel  industry. 

Mr.  Feller.  Let's  assume  a  constant  price,  then.  Assuming  that 
the  price  is  not  raised,  the  price  remains  at  the  present  level.  On  the 
cost  curve  that  you  showed  us  a  while  back  wouldn't  it  follow  that  the 
increment  to  profit  which  results  from  increases  in  the  rate  of  opera- 
tions would  progressively  get  smaller  and  smaller? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Perhaps  I  can  deal  with  that  question  in  terms  of  this 
chart.  This  is  chart  B-3  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409"  \  entitled  "Relation- 
ship Between  Sales  and  Costs.  Effects  of  Reduction  from  Average 
1938  Prices."  The  solid  black  line  in  this  chart  represents  the  total 
cost  under  1938  price,  wage  rate,  tax  rate,  and  other  conditions  at 
various  volumes  of  production.  The  double  line  represents  what  sales 
and  revenues  would  have  been  at  various  rates  of  operations  with  1938 
prices.  Now  the  second  question  which  you  put  to  me  might  be 
answered  in  this  way.  If  you  took,  for  example,  the  rate  of  operation 
at  14,000,000  of  weighted  tons  of  all  products  shipped,  the  difference 
between  this  double  line  and  the  solid  black  line  would  represent  the 
profit  under  1938  conditions,  with  the  exclusion  of  such  items  as  we 
have  recognized.  If  we  drop  do^vn  to  7,000,000  tons,  the  income  would 
then  have  been  less  than  the  cost,  so  a  reduction  in  rate  of  operations 
from  14,000,000  weighted  tons  to  7,000,000  weighted  tons  would  have 
converted  a  profit  into  a  loss.  That  is  based  upon  the  assumption  that 
there  is  no  change  in  prices. 

'  Appendix,  p.  13777. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER  13607 

Dr.  Keeps.  And  on  the  additional  assumption  that  the  costs  which 
you  show  for  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  are  costs  that  apply 
to  every  other  corporation  in  the  industry. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  that  is  quite  right.  My  remarks  here  don't 
apply  to  the  ether  corporations  in  the  industry.  I  am  talking  now 
about  the  relation  between  price  levels  and  costs  for  the  Steel  Cor- 
poration. 

(Mr.  O'Connell  assumed  the  Chair.) 

Mr.  Feller.  The  reason  you  have  those  two  lines  is  this,  isn't  it: 
That  there  are  $200,000,000  approxiniately  of  fixed  costs,  $200,000,000 
of  costs  which  never  vary,  which  are  invariable.  Your  variable  costs, 
however,  you  have  shown  go  up  in  a  straight  hne.     Your  sales  line 

Dr.  Yntema  (interposing).  Pardon  me,  the  variable  costs  per  unit 
remain  constant.  The  aggregate  of  all  variable  costs  goes  up  in  a 
straight  line. 

Mr.  Feller.  The  variable  costs  per  unit  remain  constant.  There- 
fore, the  only  possibility  of  making  an  increased  profit  on  increased 
rate  of  operations,  the  price  remaining  the  same,  is  in  that  $200,000,000, 
fixed  cost.     That  is  right,  isn't  it? 

Dr.  Yntema.  There  are  many  ways  of  saying  this.  One  way  of 
putting  it  is  as  follows:  If  the  price  is  above  the  initial  cost  the  larger 
the  number  of  imits  you  sell  at  that  price  the  larger  the  profit.  That  is 
apparent,  because  if  you  increase  your  volume. the  income  increases 
more  rapidly  than  the  costs  for  producing  and  supplying  the  product. 
If  the  price  were  to  be  brought  below  the  variable  costs,  the  losses 
would  go  up  as  the  volume  increased.  If  the  price  were  exactly  equal 
to  the  variable  cost,  the  total  loss  would  be  equal  to  the  overhead, 
no  matter  what  the  volume. 

I  should  like  to  make  one  comment  parenthetically,  if  I  may.  Any 
statistician  of  any  competence  would  know  that  you  cannot,  by 
fitting  a  straight  hne  to  a  series  of  points,  show  that  that  is  precisely 
the  true  functional  relation  between  one  variable  and  the  other. 
But  you  can  say,  if  the  points  approach  very  closely  to  a  straight  line, 
that  it  represents  to  a  reasonable  degree  of  approximation,  the  func- 
tional relation  in  question.  I  don't  want  to  be  quoted  as  saying  that 
the  additional  costs  are  precisely  $55.73,  and  that  they  stay  precisely 
constant.  I  would  say  that  the  evidence  we  have  surveyed  indicates 
that  that  is  a  reasonable  approximation  to  the  facts. 

Dr.  Kreps.  To  the  facts  for  the  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation? 

Dr.  Yntema.  To  the  facts  for  the  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Which  you  are  applying  to  the  entire  industry? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No.  Now,  let's  make  clear  two  "types  of  things. 
What  I  am  suggesting  is  this:  Not  that  for  the  entire  industry  the 
cost  fimction  would  be  identical  with  this,  but  that  the  operations  of 
producing  steel  are  somewhat  similar  in  the  other  steel  corporations. 

Dr.  Kreps.  But  the  results  are  dissimilar  as  shown  by  the  proved 
records  of  the  various  corporations,  are  they  not? 

Dr.  Yntema.  If  I  may  continue,  the  operations  are  similar,  and 
if  you  were  to  construct  a  cost  function  for  the  other  corporations 
in  the  industry,  you  would  find,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  somewhat  the 
same  type  ©f  pattern.  Where  the  profit  margins  are  larger,  you  would 
find,  of  course,  that  the  cost  line  would  be  lower  in  relation  to  the 


13608        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

income  line;  where  the  proj&t  margins  are  narrower,  you  would  find 
that  the  cost  line  was  higher  in  relation  to  the  price  and  income  line. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Do  you  have 

Dr.  Yntema  (interposing).  Just  a  minute.  If  the  committee  would 
like  to  see  a  chart  which  was  prepared,  which  hasn't  yet  come  from 
the  drafting  office,  we  will  be  glad  to  submit  this  afternoon  an  exhibit 
which  shows  the  unadjusted  cost  figures  for  a  number  of  concerns  in 
the  steel  industry.  Now,  those  costs  have  not  been  adjusted.  They 
are  not  comparable  strictly  to  what  we  have  had  presented  to  the  com- 
mittee, but  I  think  they  wiU  throw  some  light  on  this  problem  and 
we  will  be  glad  to  offer  them.     They  are  not  our  own  figures. 

Dr.  Keeps.  I  want  to  pursue  one  point  just  a  little  further. 
This  cost  line  is  the  cost  line  for  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation 
is  it  not? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct;  under  IP'"^  conditions. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Quite.  You  make  no  .  nptions  what  it  would  be 
for  other  competitors,  let's  say,  in  the  steel  industry? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No,  we  make  no  assumptions  because  we  have  said 
nothing  about  that  except  implicitly  to  this  extent:  I  have  made  no 
detailed  study  other  than  what  appears  in  this  chart.  We  haven't 
access  to  the  figures  of  our  competitors.  I  wish  we  did.  It  would 
be  a  very  interesting  study  to  make,  to  compare  the  cost  functions  of 
other  companies  in  the  ind  stry.     [Laughter. j 

My  judgment  is  this,  t  at  because  the  operations  are  somewhat 
similar  and  because  the  companies  have  to  compete  in  the  same 
markets  generally  for  the  services  and  products  which  are  employed, 
the  cost  functions  would  be  somewhat  similar.  Now,  there  would 
be  a  difference  due  to  the  degree  of  integration.  The  lower  the  degree 
of  integration  in  the  companies,  the  smaller  would  be  the  fixed  or 
overhead  cost  and  the  higher  would  be  the  variable  cost.  So  that  I 
should  suspect,  if  anything,  that  the  other — that  many  of  the.  other 
smaller  companies  in  the  industry  would  have  a  comparatively  smaller 
proportion  of  overhead  costs.  But  I  am  merely  inferring  that,  and 
I  can't  say  it  with  any  certainty. 

Mr.  Fellee.  Dr.  Yntema,  I  just  want  to  get  the  exact  significance 
of  your  testimony  with  relation  to  costs.  Did  I  understand  this  to 
be  correct,  that  looking  at  the  chart,  which  I  think  is  B-2,  the  largest 
segment  in  the  sloping  part,  the  variable  cost  part,  is  taken  up  by 
pay-roll? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct. 

Mr.  Feller.  Now,  your  testimony  is  to  this  effect,  that  at  aU  rates 
of  operation,  once  the  Corporation  has  passed  this  $200,000,000  fixed 
cost,  at  all  rates  of  operation,  the  unit  cost  of  labor  per  ton  of  steel  is 
constant;  is  that  correct? 

Dr  Yntema.  Well,  the  additional  cost,  of  additional  labor  per 
ton  of  all  products  is  approximately  constant,  and  that  is  borne  out 
by  other  studies  we  have  made.  I  think  that  is  a  very  reasonable 
approximation  of  fact. 

Mr.  Feller.  I  just  wanted  to  get  that  clear. 

Dr.  Yntema.  It  is  conceivable  that  some  conditions  might  exist 
under  which  that  might  not  be  true,  but  that,  I  think,  is  the  fair 
approximation  to  a  description  of  the  facts. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13609 

This  next  chart  is  numbered  B-6  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409,"  '  and  is 
entitled  "Relationship  Between  Sales  and  Costs.  Effect  of  Reduction 
from  2nd  Half  1938  Prices."  It  is  similar  to  chart  B-3  in  "Exhibit 
No.  1409"  ^  except  for  the  fact  that  the  sales  and  revenue  line  is 
based  upon  the  price  levels  prevailing  in  the  second  half  of  1938  instead 
of  the  full  year  of  1938. 

In  the  middle  of  1938  there  occurred  a  substantial  reduction  in 
steel  prices,  and  this  gives  effect  to  that  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel. 
As  a  consequence  of  that  reduction  the  break-even  point  before  any 
provision  for  return  on  preferred  or  common  stocks,  rose  to  approxi- 
mately 50  or  55  percent.  If  the  price  were  further  reduced  10  percent 
from  the  level  prevailing  in  the  second  half  of  1938,  and  if  the  other 
conditions  in  the  year  1938  had  prevailed,  the  break-even  point  would 
have  risen  to  90  percent;  in  other  words,  under  the  wage  rates,  tax 
rates  and  price  levels  prevailing  in  1938,  a  price  level  10  percent 
lower  than  the  price  level  prevailing  in  the  second  half  of  that  year 
would  have  necessitated  an  operating  rate  for  the  Steel  Corporation  of 
90  percent,  merely  to  cover  its  costs  without  any  allowance  for  return 
to  the  stockholders.  If  there  had  been  included  a  provision  of  5  per- 
cent of  return  on  the  total  investment  in  the  Steel  Corporation,  that  is, 
the  total  assets  less  the  current  liabilities,  the  break-even  point  would 
have  had  to  be  130  percent. 

That  provides  some  evidence  as  to  the  possibilities  further  of 
reductions  in  prices  from  the  level  prevailing  in  the  second  half  of  that 
year. 

Since  that  time,  there  have  not  been  major  changes  in  the  published 
prices  of  steel  products. 

Mr.  Wooden,  I  take  it  that  means,  however,  that  it  would  not  be 
necessary  to  have  a  130  percent  rate  of  operation  necessarily  for 
other  units  or  other  members  of  the  industry? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No,  it  would  not.  For  some  it  probably  would  be 
necessary  to  have  higher  rates  than  that  and  for  others  lower  rates. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Have  you  gone  into  that  question? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No,  we  havie  not.  As  I  said,  in  order  to  make  a 
complete  study,  I  think  this  should  be  done  for  all  the  operating  units 
in  the  steel  industry,  but  that,  of  course,  is  not  within  our  province. 
We  made  a  preliminary  study  and  I  think  in  all  likelihc  od  when  you 
completed  such  a  study,  you  wouldn't  find  greatly  different  results 
from  those  we  have  shown  here,  but  that  again  is  a  matter  of  opinion 
based  upon  the  Examination  only  of  limited  published  evidence. 

This  next  chart  is  numbered  B-7  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409,"  ^  It 
shows  the  increases  in  volume  needed  to  compensate  for  various 
decreases  in  second-half  1938  prices,  compared  with  the  probable 
resulting  increases  in  volume.  There  is  no  need  to  describe  the  chart 
in  detail.     It  is  similar  to  the  chart  preceding. 

What  it  shows  is  that  if  there  were  to  be  decreases  from  the  price 
level  prevailing  in  the  second  half  of  1938,  the  increases  in  volume 
necessary  to  compensate  for  the  price  decrease  and  leave  no  further 
loss,  would  have  been  still  greater  than  in  the  chart  which  you  have 
just  seen. 

'  Appendix,  p.  13783. 
'  Appendix,  p.  13777. 
'Appendix,  p.  13785. 


13610       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMU^  POWER 

This  next  chart  is  numbered  B-9  inj  "Exhibit^ No.  1409"  ^  and  is 
entitled  "Unadjusted  Costs  and  Volume^of  Business  Compared  with 
Estimated  Costs  for  Corresponding  Volumes  under  1938  Conditions." 
We  have  inserted  in  tliis  chart  a  line  showinp  the  relation  between 
adjusted  cost,  that  is,  adjusted  to  1938  conditions,  and  volume  of 
production.  We  have  also  inserted  in  this  chart  the  actual  costs, 
not  the  adjusted  costs,  but  the  actual  costs  in  these  respective  years. 

Some  interesting  observations  might  be  made  from  this  chart. 
One  is  that  the  level  of  cost  prevailing  in  1938  at  various  volumes  of 
output  is  this  line,  which  represents  what  the  cost  would  have  been 
under  the  1938  wage  rate,  tax  rate  and  price  conditions  at  various 
volumes  of  output  for  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation.  The  cost 
level  of  output  under  1938  conditions  was  substantially  higher  than  it 
had  been  in  the  years  preceding;  that  is,  the  net  effect  of  the  price 
changes  and  increases  in  wage  rates,  has  been  to  increase  substantially 
the  cost  of  production  of  steel,  at  least  insofar  as  the  evidence  to  be 
obtained  from  the  operations  of  the  Steel  Corporation  is  concerned. 

Now,  it  is  possible,  as  I  will  show  in  the  chart  to  follow,  to  compute 
an  index  by  taking  the  ratio  of  the  actual  costs  in  1929  to  what  the 
costs  would  have  been  under  1938  conditions  for  that  volume,  the  ratio 
of  the  costs  in  1930' to  what  the  costs  would  have  been  under  1938 
conditions  for  that  volume,  and  thus  to  get  an  index  of  what  the 
actual  costs  were  to  what  they  would  have  been  under  1938  con- 
ditions.    Let  me  present  that  in  the  following  chart. 

This  chart  is  numbered  C-25  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409."  ^  It  is  entitled, 
"Composite  Mill  Net  Yield  and  Cost  per  Weighted  Ton  Shipped. 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries."  The  lines  repre- 
sent index  numbers.  The  dotted  Hne  depicts  an  index  of  the  average 
actual  cost  per  weighted  ton  of  products  shipped.  The  actual  cost 
per  ton — average  actual  cost  per  ton — reflects  the  effect  of  changes 
in  wage  rates,  changes  in  material  prices  and  prices  of  services,  changes 
in  tax  rates  and  also  changes  in  the  volume  of  production."  The 
average  costs  tend  to  go  up — do  go  up — as  the  volume  of  production 
declines,  because  the  fixed  costs  are  then  spread  over  a  smaller  number 
of  units  of  output. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Dr.  Yntema,  would  you  explain  the  relationship 
between  these  curves  and  profits?  You  do  not  mean  to  imply  by  the 
fact  that  your  index  of  composite  mill  net  yield  is  below  the  index  of 
costs,  from  1929  on,  that  there  has  been  no  year  in  which  the  Corpor- 
ation has  made  a  profit,  do  you? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  Dr.  Kreps.  ,1  was  coming  to  that  point  in  just 
a  moment.  I  should  like  to  take  these  curves  and  explain  what  each 
of  them  is  and  then  come  to  your  question.  That  is  a  point  which 
should  be  made  clear  in  the  discussion  of  this  chart. 

This  second  double  line  represents,  on  the  basis  of  the  chart  we 
have  just  shown,  an  estimate  of  what  the  costs  would  have  been  in 
these  various  years  under  the  wage  rate  conditions,  the  tax  conditions, 
and  the  material  price  conditions  in  those  various  years,  but  with  the 
volume  of  production  which  had  existed  in  1926. 

Now,  this  is  to  some  extent  arbitrary,  but  I  think  it  is  none  the  less 
a  rather  useful  separation  of  the  effects  of  two  factors — the  cflects  of 

'  Appendix,  p.  13789. 
>  Appendix,  p.  13835. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13611 

changes  in  volume  upon  average  cost,  and  the  effects  of  all  factors 
taken  together. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Wouldn't  you  like  to  add  to  that,  if  you  were  an  execu- 
tive of  the  Steel  Corporation,  you  might  be  looking  around  to  see 
whether  you  had  maintained  your  efficiency? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  we  should  add 

Dr.  Kreps  (interposing).  Wouldn't  this  sort  of  a  chart,  sort  of 
arrest  the  attention  of  executives  and  make  them  wonder  whether  the 
efficiency  of  their  operations  was  quite  as  great  as  it  had  been  a  few 
years  previous? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Well,  I  am  not  competent  to  appraise  in  any  way  the 
efficiency  of  operations  in  the  steel  industry. 

Dr.  Kreps.  At  any  rate,  you  have  made  no  correction  of  any  kind 
for  efficiency,  have  you? 

Dr.  Yntema.  This  is  true :  Yes ;  we  have  in  some  of  our  studies  made 
a  correction  for  efficiency,  and  there  has  been  a  definite  dovvTiward 
trend  in  costs  in  the  Steel  Corporation  which  I  think  can  be  attributable 
only  to  increases  in  efficiency,  and  that  is  shown  in  the  material  pre- 
sented in  "Exhibit  No.  1416,"  ^  entitled  "An  Analysis  of  Steel  Prices, 
Volume,  and  Costs — Controlhng  Limitations  on  Price  Reductions." 
There  is  a  downward  trend  in  costs  over  the  period  studied,  which  does 
reflect  the  increases  in  efficiency. 

But  to  come  back  to  this — this  actual  cost  per  ton  of  products 
shipped  would  have  been  higher  at  this  point  if  there  had  been  no 
increases  in  efficiency.  This  represents  the  net  effect  of  all  factors, 
and  if  there  had  been  no  increase  in  eflLciency,  this  cost  line,  starting 
from  100  here  (this  is  an  index  number),  would  not  have  been  as  low 
at  the  end  as  it  actually  was.  This  does  represent  a  considerable 
increase  in  efficiency,  in  comparison  with  the  effept  of  other  factors. 

Dr.  Keeps.  An  efficiency  which  did  not,  however,  actuaUy  lower 
actual  costs? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No.  The  point  is  this,  that  the  increase  in  efficiency 
was  a  component  tending  to  bring  down  average  costs.  The  increase 
in  efficiency  was  not  as  great  as  the  increase  in  other  costs,  particularly 
wage  rateSi 

I  think  it  is  beyond  doubt  true  that  the  wage  rates  in  the  Steel  Cor- 
poration have  gone  up  faster  than  the  efficiency  of  production,  and 
that  is  the  primary  reason  why  the  costs  per  unit  of  product  are  higher 
in  these  latter  years  than  they  were  in  the  earlier  years. 

'Dr.  Kreps.  You  have  charts,  I  take  it,  that  show  the  break-down 
of  costs  and  show  the  increasing  efficiency? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is,  as  I  just  said,  presented  in  a  summary  fashion 
m  "Exhibit  No.  1416."  We  have  not  made  extensive  studies  with 
reference  to  that.  I  personally  am  not  competent  to  pass  on  the 
subject,  because  that  would  require 

Dr.  Keeps  (interposing).  I  missed  the  detailed  study.  I  did  see  the 
assertion. 

Dr., Yntema.  Yes.  The  group  with  which  I  worked  simply  is  not 
competent  to  engage  in  a  study  of  that  sort,  and  if  you  wish  to  request 
someone,  Mr.  Fairless-  or  someone  from  the  Steel  Corporation,  who  is 
competent  to  respond  to  that  question,  I  am  sure  he  would  be  glad  to 
do  so.     But  I  don't  feel  competent  to  answer  the  question. 

'  Appendix,  p.  14032. 

124491— U—pt.  20 3 


13612       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

If  I  may  come  back  to  chart  C-25  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409"  '  the  double 
line  represents,  then,  what  the  costs  would  have  been,  allowing  for 
changes  in  wage  rates,  tax  rates,  and  efficiency,  but  eliminating  the 
eflFect  of  changes  in  volume.  Now,  it  is  subject  to  deficiencies,  but 
on  the  other  hand,  it  is  as  satisfactory  a  result  as  we  could  obtain, 
and  we  have  shown  you  how  we  have  obtained  it. 

We  have  also  plotted  here  in  the  third  fine  the  composite  mill  net 
yield  to  the  Corporation.  This  represents,  as  satisfactorily  as  we  have 
been  able  to  obtain  it,  a  measure  of  the  price  levels  of  the  products  sold 
by  the  Corporation, 

Now,  the  point  was  made  earlier  that  the  price  level  paid  by  those 
who  buy  the  products  may  be  slightly  different  in  its  behavior  from 
the  price  level  of  the  prices  obtained  by  the  Corporation.  Those 
differences,  in  my  opinion,  are  negligible.  It  is  the  differences  in  the 
fluctuations  of  those  series,  I  think,  that  are  negligible,  and  I  believe 
this  is  a  satisfactory  picture. 

Mr.  Feller.  May  I  ask  a  question? 

Dr.  Yntema.  May  I  go  on  one  moment  to  complete  this  so  we 
won't  break  the  structure  of  the  argument? 

Mr.  Feller.  I  would  like  to  interrupt  you,  if  I  may,  to  get  on 
what  basis  those  two  lines  were  plotted.  You  said  the  products  sold 
by  the  Corporation — you  mean  the  steel  products,  or  all  products? 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  composite  mill  net  yield  covers  only  the  steel 
products.  On  the  other  hand,  "only  the  steel  products"  includes 
the  great  bulk,  all  but  a  relatively  small  percent,  of  the  goods  and 
services  sold  by  the  Corporation. 

Mr.  Feller.  That  line  which  is  above,  designated  actual  cost 

Dr.  Yntema  (interposing).  That  represents  all  costs  of  all  prod- 
ucts.    The  reason  we  have  not 

Mr.  Feller  (interposing).  And  of  all  subsidiaries? 

Dr.  Yntema.  And  of  all  subsidiaries. 

Mr.  Feller.  Including  transportation  systems? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Including  all  subsidiaries. 

Mr.  Feller.  That's  all.     I  just  wanted  to  get  that  clear. 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  reason  for  handling  the  problem  this  way  's  that 
any  separation  would  involve  an  arbitrary  allocation  of  costs.  It 
would  also  involve  a  tremendous  amount  of  work.  I  don't  think  that 
if  you  made  the  separation  the  results  would  be  substantially  different 
from  these. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Dr.  Yntema,  did  you  have  access  to  any  unit  costs  of 
production,  or  did  you  make  any  study  of  the  changes  in  unit  costs  as 
compared  to  the  labor  costs  per  unit  of  production? 

Dr.  Yntema.  What  do  you  mean  by  unit  costs  of  production? 

Mr.  Wooden.  Per  ton  cost  of  production. 

Dr.  Yntema.  You  mean  the  average  costs  of  production  per  ton? 

Mr.  Wooden.  Yes. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes,  I  have  seem  some  of  those.  In  such  a  case,  in 
case  of  any  manufacturing  operations,  where  there  are  multiple  prod- 
ucts produced,  it  is  possible  to  make  some  fairly  satisfactory  study  of 
the  costs  immediately  associated  with  each  process,  but  when  the 
oveihead  is  allocated,  the  allocation  becomes  arbitrary.  We  were 
inter,  sted  in  this  study  not  just  in  the  direct  costs,  but  in  all  the  costs 
of  operation,  so  although  I  have  seen  some  of  the  unit  costs  and  I 

'  Appendix,  p.  13835. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13613 

have  studied  the  behavior  of  mill  costs  to  some  extent,  those  were  not 
appropriate  for  this  particular  problem  and  we  have  not  presented 
them  to  the  committee.  .  In  fact,  I  don't  think  that  they  are  in  form 
to  be  particularly  illuminating  on  the  problems  which  concern  the 
committee  and  we  have  chosen  from  our  material  that  which  we 
thought  would  be  most  useful  to  you. 

If  I  may  continue,  this  third  line  is  an  index  of  the  composite  mill 
net  yield  of  steel  products.  It  is  the  best  index  we  have  been  able  to 
present,  showing  the  price  level  of  the  prices  obtained  by  the  Corpora- 
tion. This  chart  is  important  because  of  the  light  it  throws  on  price 
flexibility.  When  you  talk  of  price  flexibility,  there  are,  of  course, 
many  criteria  which  you  might  use.  You  might  talk  of  price  flexi- 
bility with  respect  to  what  the  prices  have  been  or  were  at  some  later 
tima,  or  you  might  talk  of  price  flexibility  in  relation  to  costs. 

This,  in  a  sense,  is  a  picture  of  price  flexibility  in  relation  to  costs. 
As  we  proceed  from  1929  to  1932,  we  see  that  the  actual  average  cost 
per  ton  went  up  sharply,  and  that  the  average  miU  net  yield  declined. 
We  find,  however,  that  the  cost  prices,  that  an  index  of  the  cost  prices, 
if  I  may  use  that  term,  did  not  drop  as  much  as  the  prices  which  the 
Corporation  got  for  its  products.  In  other  words,  the  Corporation, 
during  the  depression,  dropped  the  prices  for  its  products  more  than 
the  prices  which  it  paid  for  the  goods  and  services  which  it  used  in 
the  production  of  those  products. 

It  suffered,  therefore,  on  two  counts:  First,  because  the  price  level, 
or  the  prices  of  products  and  services  which  it  sold,  dropped  more 
than  the  price  level  of  the  products  and  services  which  it  bought; 
and  second,  because  of  the  decrease  in  volume,  which  meant  that  the 
overhead  or  fixed  cost  was  spread  over  a  smaller  number  of  units.    " 

To  come  back  to  an  earlier  question  which  we  should  make  perfectly 
clear  in  this  connection,  these  do  not  represent  prices  or  cost  per  unit. 
It  is  not  possible  in  the  chart  in  this  case  to  represent  those,  for  the 
reason  that  the  units  are  not  the  same.  We  took  1926  as  a  base. 
In  1926,  the  Steel  Corporation  realized  6.2  percent  return  on  its  invest- 
ment. We  have  not  taken,  therefore,  I  think,  an  unreasonable  base 
for  the  chart. 

If  this  black  line  and  this  dotted  line  had  remained  at  the  same 
level,  and  allowing  for  any  possible  imperfections  in  this  index  number, 
since  we  do  not  claim  it  to  be  absolutely  perfect,  the  return  on  invest- 
ment would  have  stayed  approximately  at  6.2  percent.  The  return 
ofi  investment  dropped  and  became  negative  because  costs  went  up 
in  relation  to  prices  in  this  period. 

In  1937  there  was  a  profit  available,  again  because  the  ayerage 
prices  rose  up  to  meet  the  average  costs.  I  think  this  does  afford  some 
interesting  evidence,  at  least,  on  the  general  problems  of  price  flexi- 
bility. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  Dr.  Yntema,  if  I  may  interrupt  you, 
would  this  be  a  convenient  time  to  recess?  Are  you  through  with 
this  particular  chart? 

Dr.  Yntema.  This  is  almost  the  end  of  my  statement. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  Then  would  you  care  to  conclude? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes.  In  brief,  our  studies  show  that  the  demand  for 
steel  is  determined  primarily  by  general  business  activity,  consumers' 
income-  and  industrial  profits,  and  to  Only  a  minor  extent  by  the  price 
of  steel.     The  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  is  so  low  that  a  reduction 


13614       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

in  steel  prices  does  not  provide  an  effective  means  of  increasing  pro- 
duction and  employment  in  the  industry.  Because  of  this  inelastic 
demand  and  the  character  of  costs  in  the  industry,  a  moderate  decrease 
in  price  results  in  a  great  decrease  in  profits  or  increase  in  losses.  Since 
margins  of  profit  in  the  steel  industry  during  the  past  10  years  have 
been  and  still  are  extremely  low,  no  substantial  reduction  in  steel 
prices  could  have  been  borne  or  could  now  be  borne  by  the  industry 
without  corresponding  reductions  in  costs.  This  could  not  be  effected 
without  great  reductions  in  wage  rates. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  should  say  by  the  Steel  Corporation,  shouldn't 
you? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  I  should  say  by  the  steel  industry.  According 
to  the  figures  which  are  submitted  in  your  own  record,  the  average 
earnings  in  the  steel  industry  have  been  extremely  low  in  the  last  10 
years. 

Dr.  Kreps.  For  all  the  plants? 

Dr  Yntema.  Not  for  all  the  individual  plants  but  the  average  for 
all  of  them  is  extremely  low.     I  think  that  is  a  mild  statement. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  Very  high  perhaps  from  1901  on  to  1930? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  am  not  talking  about  that;  I  am  talking  about 
things  as  they  are  in  this  particular  statement. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Your  evidence,  in  other  words,  does  not  show  that  this 
is  true  for  the  industry ;  it  does  show  that  it  is  true  for  the  Corporation? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No  ;  we  are  referring  to  figures  submitted  in  the  record 
by  your  own  research  group  on  this  particular  point.  We  didn't  think 
it  necessary  to  supplement  that. 

Dr.  Kreps.  But  your  comment  concerns  what  you  believe  has  been 
inserted  in  the  record  about  other  corporations? 

Dr.  Yntema.  It  is  my  comment  on  what  has  been  inserted  in  the 
record,  and  also  my  comment  as  ^to  what  I  believe  to  be  the  facts  of 
the  case  on  the  basis  of  such  evidence  as  is  available  to  me 

A  substantial  reduction  in  prices  could  not  be  effected  without 
great  reductions  in  wage  rates. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  Dr.  Yntema,  do  you  know  how  many  industries  in 
the  United  States  there  are  in  which  steel  is  a  factor  in  cost  of  produc- 
tion? I  mean,  steel  is  sold  to  them  as  their  fabricating  product  and 
the  purchase  of  steel  is  a  facior  in  production. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  should  say  there  are  practically  no  industries  in  the 
United  States  in  which  steel  is  not  used,  either  as  a  raw  material  or  in 
the  form  of  machinery,  but  I  think  it  ought  to  be  added  immediately 
that  the  cost  of  the  steel,  in  proportion  to  other  costs  in  niost  of  those 
industries,  is  negligible,  and  even  in  the  case  of  the  major  steel 
consuming  industries,  the  proportion  of  the  cost  of  steel  to  the  other 
costs  is  very  low;  it  is  very  low,  as  we  have  pointed  out. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  Dr.  Kreps,  do  you  intend  to  recall 
Dr.  Yntema? 

Dr.  Kreps.  Yes;  I  should  like  to  recall  Dr.  Yntema  after  we  have 
heard  certain  other  witnesses.  Before  dismissing,  Dr.  Yntema,  I 
should  like,  on  behalf  of  all  of  'us  who  have  examined  the  data,  to 
express  high  tribute,  not  only  to  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation 
but  to  Dr.  Yntema  personally,  for'  the  many  new  item's  of  information 
which  they  have  given  to  the  committee  and  to  economists  and 
businessmen  througho  it  the  country. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13615 

If  I  may,  I  should  like  to  summarize  some  of  these  for  the  committee. 
New  information  has  been  made  available  in  three  fields,  those  of 
costs,  prices  and  labor.  As  you  have  noticed,  the  material  on  costs 
not  only  presents  break-downs  which  are  entirely  new,  but  even  some 
that  are  probably  unknown  to  most  firms  in  the  industry  at  least  in 
the  form  in  which  they  have  been  presented.  Some  of  the  items  shown 
are,  first,  total  costs  of  the  Corporation  after  the  elimination  of  results 
of  intercompany  transactions;  break-down  of  the  costs  into  a  number 
of  components,  that  is,  taxes,  wages,  material  coste  and  depreciation, 
and  a  measurement  of  the  year-to-year  changes  in  these  cost  factors. 

Closely  associated  with  this  new  break-down  of  cost  figures  is  the 
additional  information  furnished  on  income  from  operations;  also 
adjusted  for  inter-company  transactions.  In  the  field  of  prices,  the 
outstanding  contribution  in  our  judgment  is  the  making  available  of 
data  on  actual  mill  nets,  hitherto,  of  course,  regarded  as  roughly 
corresponding  to  prices.  There  has  been  a  long,  and  I  think  rather 
sterile,  controversy  concerning  the  degree  to  which  these  pubhshed 
prices  actually  represented  prices  paid.  The  new  materials  on  the 
miU  nets  received  by  subsidiaries  of  the 'United  States  Steel  Corpora 
tion  give  this  information  not  only  for  steel  in  general,  but  for  various 
types  of  steel.  This  goes  far  beyond  any  previously  published  data 
and  should  make  unnecessary  extended  continuation  of  much  of  the 
dispute  concerning  the  significance  of  published  prices. 

Similarly  in  the  field  of  labor,  there  are  new  break-downs  of  wages 
and  employment,  and  new  information  extending  over  a  number  of 
years  on  hours,  wage  rates  and  weekly  earnings  of  employees. 

I  should  like  to  have  it  distinctly  understood  that  what  we  now 
propose  is  nothing  else  than  a  cooperative  examination  and  an  explora- 
tion of  this  new  and  vital  information.  Whatever  differences  there 
are,  are  largely  differences  of  evaluation.  They  can  be  classified  into 
three  groups:  First,  we  question,  or  rather,  we  want  to  examine  the 
adequacy  of  some  of  the  assumptions.  Part  of  that  has  already  come 
out  in  this  morning's  discussion.  Our  next  witness.  Dr.  deChazeau, 
will  dwell  on  that  topic. 

It  is  important  constantly  to  keep  in  mind  that  the  mathematical 
techniques  used  depend  upon  and  are  determined  by  the  economic 
hypotheses,  or  economic  assumptions,  which  one  makes.  For 
mathematics  is  just  a  hopper  which  grinds  out  more  or  less  finely  what 
one  puts  in  We  beheve  that  if  one  accepts  Dr.  Yntema's  arbitrary 
and  limitr'l  economic  assumptions  as  being  adequate  and  valid  for 
the  commiitee,  that  is,  if  the  committee  does  not  consider  any  other 
assumptions  but  those,  then  little  substantial  modification  is  possible 
in  the  presentation  by  Dr.  Yntema  as  given  to  the  committee. 

Secondly,  we  shall  want  to  examine  various  aspects  of  certain  of 
the  cost  items.  Finally,  there  are  a  few  things  that  should  be  pointed 
out  about  the  correlation  techniques.  But  I  hope  that  nothing  that 
shall  be  presented  by, the  witnesses  who  are  to  come  will  in  any  way 
detract  from  this  tribute  which  we  collectively  wish  to  make  to  the 
Steel  Corporation  and  to  Dr.  Yntema.  We  will  call  Dr.  Melvin 
deChazeau  this  afternoon. 

Mr.  Wooden.  I  have  a  few  questions  I  would  like  to  ask  of  Dr. 
Yntema.     May  that  be  postponed  until  the  first  thing  this  afternoon? 
Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  Dr.  Elreps,  had  you  intended  recall- 
ing Dr.  Yntema?^ 


13616       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Dr.  Keeps.  Dr.  Yntema  will  be  recalled,  because  it  is  our  proposal, 
Mr.- Chairman,  after  Dr.  deChazeau  has  presented  his  statement,  to 
ask  Dr.  Yntema  to  make  comments.  In  fact,  it  is  our  proposal  that 
such  a  procedure  be  followed  for  each  of  the  witnesses.  This  is  a 
cooperative  exploration.  There  are  large  areas  of  debatability  and 
legitimate  differences  of  opinion.  It  is  difficult  to  appraise  new  infor- 
mation. Pioneering  efforts  are  always  subject  to  reevaluation.  We 
would  really  like  to  know  what  it  is  we  have  on  our  hands. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  Mr.  Wooden,  would  you  prefer  to 
have  Dr.  Yntema  recalled  immediately  after  lunch  for  your  questions? 

Mr.  Wooden.  It  makes  no  difference. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell,  Then  since  we  are  going  to  have  Dr. 
Yntema  a  little  later  on,  let's  recess  and  hear  Dr.  deChazeau  after 
lunch.     We  stand  in  recess  Imtil  2:30. 

(Whereupon,  at  12:40  p.  m.,  a  recess  was  taken  until  2:30  p.  m.  of 
the  same  day.) 

AFTERNOON    SESSION 

(The  hearing  was  resumed  at  2:35  p.  m.,  on  the  expiration  of  the 
recess.) 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  The  committee  will  please  be  in 
order. 

Dr.  KJreps, 

Dr.  Kreps.  Mr.  Chairman,  before  we  resume  the  steel  hearings,  I 
should  like  to  finish  the  presentation  of  the  cartel  hearings,  because  due 
to  the  death  of  Senator  Borah,  the  senior  senatorial  member  of  the 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  its  cartel  hearings  \v"rr 
ended  before  it  was  possible  to  place  the  last  witness.  Dr.  Rudolf 
Callmann  on  the  stand.  Dr.  Callmann,  now  residing  at  23  Hammond 
Street,  Cambridge,  Mass.,  is  an  internationally  recognized  authority 
on  cartel  problems. 

For  the  10-year  period  just  prior  to  1936,  when  he  was  attracted  to 
the  United  States,  he  was  Rechtsanwalt  am  Landgericht  in  Cologne, 
Germany,  engaged  in  legal  consulting  practice  for  a  variety  of  German 
catiels.  Prior  to  that  time,  for  a  period  of  4  years,  he  was  managing 
director  of  the  firm,  Rollmann  &  Mayer,  a  shoe  manufacturing  concern 
at  Cologne.  In  addition,  he  is  the  author  of  a  number  of  authoritative 
writings  on  cartel  and  related  problems,  most  important  of  which  are 
his  volumes  on  unfair  competition,  entitled  "Der  Unlautere  Wett- 
bewcrg  (J.  Bensheimer,  Mannheim-Berlin-Leipzig,  1932),  670  pages, 
and  his  -treatise  on  German  cartel  law  entitled,  "Das  Deutsche 
Kartelh-ect"  (Philo  Verlag  und  Buchhandlung  GMBG,  Berlin,  1934), 
721  pages. 

I  should  like  to  submit  his  statement,  prepared  and  sworn  to*  by 
him,  for  the  record. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell..  It  will  be  included  in  the  record  of 
the  cartel  hearings,  witlbout  objection. 

(Dr.  Callmann's  prepared  statement  on  "Cartels"  appears  in  Hear- 
ings, Part  25,  p.  13347  et  seq.). 

Dr.  Kreps.  The  first  witness  for  the  T.  N.  E.  C.  portion  of  the 
hearings,'  whom  I  should  like  to  summon,  is  Dr.  deChazeau. 

'  Hearings  on  the  steel  industry,  included  in  Hearings,  Parts  26  and  27)  were  presented  fcr  'he  staff  of  the 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  by  the  Department  of  Justice,  and  by  the  Federal  Trade 

Commission. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13617 

(Senator  King  assumed  the  Chair.) 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Have  you  been  sworn? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes,  sir. 

TESTIMONY  OF  DR.  MELVIN  G.  deCHAZEAU,  PROFESSOR  AT  THE 
UNIVERSITY  OF  VIRGINIA,  CHARLOTTESVILLE,  VA.— Resumed  ' 

Dr.  Kreps.  Dr.  deChazeau,  for  the  purpose  of  the  record,  will  you 
state  your  full  name,  please? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Melvin  G.  deChazeau. 

Dr.  Keeps.  And  you  are  now  on  the  staff  of  the  University  of 
Virginia? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes;  I  am  a  professor  there. 

Dr.  Kreps.  How  long  have  you  been  studying  problems  of  the  steel 
industry? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Beginning  in  1934,  at  which  time  I  joined  the 
staff  of  the  Bureau  of  Business  Research  of  the  University  of  Pitts- 
burgh for  a  study  of  the  steel  industry. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  are  co-author  of  two  volumes  entitled  "Economics 
of  the  Iron  and  Steel  Industry,"  published  by  McGraw-HUl  Book  Co.? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  am. 

Dr.  Kreps.  In  doing  the  research  required,  did  you  have  a  staff 
at  your  disposal. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Did  you  make  field  trips  and  did  you  go  through 
plants  and  did  you  consult  wi'th  a  number  of  steel  executives? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  We  did. 

Dr.  Kreps,  That,  I  take  it,  is  stated  in  fuU  in  this  rather  lengthy 
preface  under  the  heading,  "Obligations  to  Members  of  the  Steel 
Industry"? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  have  a  statement  which  you  have  prepared  for 
the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  on  the  material 
submitted  this  morning  by  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  have. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Will  you  please  give  that  statement? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  would  like  to  preface  my  remarks  with  a  general 
observation.  I  do  not  consider  myself  qualified  as  a  statistician  to 
criticize  in  detaU  the  technique  employed  by  Professor  Yntema. 
That  wiU  be  reserved  for  Dr.  Bean  and  for  Dr.  Ezekiel.  My  remarks, 
therefore,  are  in  the  nature  of — if  I  may  presume  to  say  so — attempt- 
ing to  present  a  point  of  view  for  the  evaluation  and  significance  of 
these  results. 

In  the  course  of  my  paper,  I  refer  to  some  possible  technical  objec- 
tions wliich  will  be  developed  more  fully  later. 

the    corporation's   analysis   of   cost   in   relation   to   volume 

Dr.  deChazeau.  The  United  States  Steel  Corporation  through  its 
subsidiaries  is  the  most  highly  integrated  steel  corporation  in  the 
industry.  It  has  always  been  supposed  that  the  more  thoroughly 
integrated  any  organization  became — that  is,  the  more  completely  it 

1  Dr.  deOhazeau's  previous  testimony  on  the  iron  and  steel  industry  appears  ip  Hearings,  Part  19. 


13618       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

insulated  the  various  stages  of  production  and  distribution  from  the 
mar-ket — the  larger  would  be  its  relatively  fixed  costs  in  comparison 
with  its  variable  costs. 

This  result  was  expected  to  follow  not  only  because  of  heavy  capital 
investment  and  the  necessary  size  of  the  corporate  structure  but  also 
because  an  integrated  structure  precluded  the  transformation  of  fixed 
into  variable  costs  which  open  market  trading  at  each  level  of  pro- 
duction provides.  The  Corporation's  analysis  of  costs  and  volume 
is  startlmg,  therefore,  in  its  apparent  demonstration,  both  that 
marginal  or  differential  costs  are  constant  over  all  observable  rates 
of  output  up  to  practical  capacity  and  that  variable  costs  per  ton  are 
so  high  relative  to  prices  received  that  the  possibility  of  price  re- 
duction without  out-of-pocket  loss  is  of  negligible  significance. 

I  should  add  here  that  I  am  not  so  much  surprised  that  the  variable 
costs  are  found  constant  in  the  steel  industry  as  I  am  surprised  at  the 
level  of  those  variable  costs.  That  is,  in  an  industry  in  which  increases 
in  output  take  place  not  through  varying  the  rate  at  which  equipment 
is  used  but  rather  in  bringing  new  items  of  equipment  into  use,  one 
would  expect  a  certain  uniformity  in  variable  costs  with  increases  in 
output.  The  thing  that  does  startle  me,  and  the  thing  which  is  crucial, 
it  seems  to  me,  in  this  analysis,  is  the  level  of  the  variable  cost  with 
relation  to  the  fixed  cost. 

This  conclusion  is  so  important  for  pubUc  pohcy  that  it  must  be 
examined  very  critically  and  exhaustively  before  it  can  be  accepted 
at  its  face  value. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  4on't  mean,  do  you  Professor,  that 
business  organizations,  whether  they  are  integrated,  or  rather,  decen- 
tralized, don't  know  what  their  costs  are? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Oh,  no. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  They  have  their  balance  sheets;  they  know 
what  the  cost  of  materials  are  which  they  purchase? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes. 

Actmg  Chairman  King.  They  know  what  they  have  received  for 
their  sales? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  They  know  what  their  wages  are,  and  at 
the  end  of  the  year,  a  balance  sheet  is  prepared  and  they  know  their 
losses  or  their  gains.    Is  that  right? 

Dr.  deChazeaq-.  That  is  right. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  And  in  periods  of  depression  or  ups  and 
downs  in  the  business  world,  obviously  there  must  be  ridges  and 
mountains  and  valleys  in  the  activities  and  the  costs  and  in  the  profits 
and  losses  of  corporations  largely  integrated?    That  is  true,  isn't  it? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes.  The  vital  tiling  here.  Senator,  is  not  so  much 
the  amoimt  of  cost  but  the  variations  of  cost,  that  is,  the  distinction 
between  the  overhead  cost  or  fixed  cost,  and  those  costs  which  vary 
with  output — that  is  {he  thing  which  is  significant  for  price  policy. 
If  the  level  of  the  curves  shown  for  total  costs  were  lower — that  is, 
less  steep — the  total  variable  cost  would  be  smaller  and  the  elasticity 
of  demand  which  would  make  profitable  a  reduction  in  price  could  be 
much  less.  Taking  the  costs  as  they  are  given  and  the  figures  as 
given,  one  would  have  to  have  a  demand  elasticity  of  close  to  four 
before  it  would  be  profitable  to  reduce  prices  on  the  basis  of  the  cost 
discussion  ^vren 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13619 

An  elasticity  of  four,  as  you  know,  means  that  with  a  given  price 
reduction  the  quantity  taken  would  be  four  times  what  it  was  before. 
Such  an  elasticity  is  beyond  that  conceived  of  by  any  students  of 
the  steel  industry,  that  or  perhaps  any  other  industry. 

For  that  reason,  it  is  vital.     That  is  the  point  to  which  I  refer. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  had  always  supposed  that  businessmen, 
whether  they  are  running  merchandising  establishments  or  steel  com- 
panies or  railroads  or  automobile  plants,  knew  what  their  profits  were 
and  knew  almost  daily  what  their  expenditures  were,  loiew  whether 
they  were  making  money  or  whether  they  were  losing  money,  and  then 
with  their  bookkeeping  systems  plus  the  experts  wliich  they  had,  busi- 
nessmen of  abihty,  who  had  been  with  many  of  the  institutions  for 
years,  would  be  enabled  to  evaluate  their  activities  and  determine  a 
proper  allocation  of  all  of  the  factors  that  were  involved  in  expendi- 
tures, profits,  and  losses. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Except  for  the  word  "allocation,"  I  should  agree 
with  you. 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  Well,  the  word  "allocation"  is  very  vital  there,  is 
it  not? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  That  is,  you  don't  question  the  fact  that  the  figures 
of  cost  as  given  are  accurate  with  reference  to  total  figures? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  No. 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  But  the  point  is  that  no  business  organization  can 
know  with  absolute  precision  what  the  distinction  between  variable 
and  fixed  costs  is?  Those  could  and  will  be  established  through 
accounting  conventions,  in  which  judgment  is  a  very  important  factor, 
and  it  is  on  that  question  of  allocation  that  you  are  raising  questions, 
not  with  reference  to  the  aggregate  figures  of  expenditure  or  the  aggre- 
gate figures  of  profit  and  loss;  is  that  correct? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  right,  with  one  addition,  if  I  may  add  it, 
Mr.  Hinrichs.  One  presumably  has  a  variation  of  cost  here  with 
changes  in  rate  of  utihzation  of  capacity,  which  is  derived  from  an 
historical  study  of  total  costs  through  the  application  of  the  correla- 
tion method.  In  the  application  of  that  method,  there  may  be 
difficulties  which  thi'ow  doubt  on  the  significance  of  the  result  from 
the  point  of  view  of  how  costs  do  in  fact  vary  with  actual  changes  in 
utihzation. 

Acting  Chairman'  King.  Proceed. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  '  The  statistical  method  employed  in  this  analysis 
of  fixed  and  variable  components  of  total  costs  involves  (a)  a  classi- 
fication of  total  expenses,  (6)  an  adjustment  of  each  category  of 
expense  to  1938  conditions,  and  (c)  an  adjustment  of  volume  of  out- 
put by  weighting  the  tonnage  of  each  class  of  products  sold  by  the 
ratio  of  its  average  mill  costs  to  the  average  mill  costs  of  all  rolled  and 
finished  steel  products  during  the  period  of  1933  through  1937. 
With  the  exception  of  pay-roll  and  "other  expense"  items  which  were 
further  adjusted  for  time  trend  to  correct  for  changes  in  efficiency,  the 
fixed  and  variable  components  in  each  expense  category  were  then 
ascertained  by  plotting  annual  adjusted  expense  against  weighted 
tonnage  sold  in  a  scatter  diagram,  fitting  a  regression  line,  and  extra- 
polating that  fine  to  the  base  line. 

There  is  always  possible  error  in  the  projection  of  a  total  expense 
function  derived  fcom  an  analysis  of  historical  cost  data.     The  shape 


13620       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

of  the  cost  function  at  levels  of  output  below  those  actually  experienced 
may  be  different  from  that  within  the  range  of  observations.  This  is 
of  slight  importance  here  since  the  low  rate  was  18  percent  of  capacity, 
very  close  to  the  absolute  minimum.  In  the  present  case,  although 
the  range  of  observations  is  wide,  the  number  of  observations,  especially 
in  the  medium  range  of  output  (i.  e.,  in  the  general  region  of  8  to  10 
million  weighted  tons),  which  is  crucial  to  the  analysis,  is  very  limited 
or  absent — I  say  crucial  because  the  break-even  point  is  around  8)^ 
million  tons.  This  fact  gravely  restricts  the  reliability  of  the  con- 
clusion that  the  total  cost  function  is  linear  and  renders  the  probable 
error  in  an  extrapolation  of  the  regression  hne  to  determine  the 
fixed  component  of  costs  extremely  high.  Fm-thermore,  a  relatively 
shght  change  in  the  slope  of  the  regression  line  can  make  a  substantial 
change  in  the  apparent  size  of  fixed  and  variable  costs.  It  is  possible, 
therefore,  that  the  actual  overhead  expense  of  the  Corporation  is 
greater  than  that  calculated  by  the  statistical  method  employed. 

Neglecting  this  possibility,  however,  it  is  apparent  that  the  character 
of  the  total  cost  function  and  the  relative  magnitude  of  fixed  and 
variable  components  of  cost  depend  on  (a)  the  dependence  of  actual 
expenses  in  a  given  year  on  the  volume  of  sales  in  that  year;  (6)  the 
reasonableness  of  the  adjustment  to  1938  conditions;  and  (c)  the 
adequacy  of  the  weights  employed  to  obtain  a  homogeneous  single 
output  series.  Finally,  the  significance  of  the  result  for  pricing  policy' 
depends  on  the  applicability  of  this  method  of  cost  analysis  to  a 
situation  in  which  multiple  plants  are  employed,  multiple  products 
manufactured,  and  dynamic  conditions  of  technology  and  capacity 
obtain. 

The  data  made  available  in  this  monograph  will  not  permit  an  ex- 
haustive or  conclusive  evaluation  of  the  results  from  the  points  of 
view  just  enumerated.  Criticisms  of  the  data  analyzed,  the  adjust- 
ment of  data,  and  especially  the  weighting  of  tons  are  important  pri- 
marily because  of  their  cumulative  rather  than  their  individual  effect. 
Because  of  the  limited  number  of  observations  a  relatively  slight 
change  in  the  location  of  points  in  the  scatter  diagrams  might  render 
the  cost  function  curvilinear  rather  than  linear.  The  most  important 
limitation  on  this  study,  however,  is  the  narrow  significance  that  may 
rightly  be  accorded  it  for  the  purposes  of  pricing  policy. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  May  I  interrupt  just  a  second  there?  If  I  under- 
stand what  you  have  just  been  saying,  it  is  that  on  the  curves  that  we 
saw  this  morning,  what  you  call  the  regression  line  here  was  that  dotted 
line  that  passed  more  or  less  through  the  points? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  right. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  And  that  in  order  to  arrive  at  a  figure  of  $162,000,- 
000  as  the  total  of  fixed  costs 

Dr.  deChazeau.  One  hundred  and  eighty-two  million  dollars. 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  It  was  necessary  to  extend  that  line  back  to  the 
theoretical  point  of  what  costs  woidd  be  even  if  there  were  no  ])roduc- 
tion.  Mr.  Yntema  made  reservations  this  morning  and  wouldn't  say 
that  those  costs  actually  >./ould  prevail  at  zero  production,  but  that 
for  practical  purposes  it  was  necessoiy  to  extend  that  line  back  to  the 
idea  of  a  zero  base  line;  that  Mr.  Yntema  this  morning  said,  if  I  re- 
member, correctly,  that  he  didn't  attach  much  importance  to  the 
extrap'.lation,  but  in  fact  it  has  a  very  real  significance  to  the  points 
that  he  was  making  because  it  is  only  when  it  is  extended  back  that 


CONCENTRATION  OF  E<^ONOMIC  POWER  13621 

that  figure  of  $182,000,000  comes  out  of  his  figures.  Now  anything 
that  happens  to  the  slope  of  that  hne,  even  if  it  involves  a  relatively 
small  shift  one  way  or  another,  might  very  well  make  that  figure 
$200,000,000  or  $150,000,000,  and  that  you  are  directing  your  atten- 
tion, therefore,  to  the  question  of  comparatively  minor  differences, 
possibly  within  the  range  of  observed  fact,  but  trying  to  see  how  vari- 
ations in  this  area  of  observation  would  affect  the  guess  that  you  have 
to  make  as  to  what  the  total  volume  of  fixed  costs  is  back  there  on  the 
line  of  zero  production.     Is  that  correct? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  true  so  far  as  the  point  with  relation  to 
extrapolation  is  concerned. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  And  if  you  were  to  have,  instead  of  a  straight  line, 
a  line  which  curved,  it  would  be  characteristic  of  a  curve  that  it  would 
drop  away  very  fast  as  it  came  back  to  that  base  line  and  flatten  off 
as  you  went  out  at  the  top.     That  is  also  correct? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes;  and  of  course  if  your  total  costs  described  a 
curve  instead  of  a  straight  line,  that  would  affect  your  conclusion  that 
the  variable  costs  were  uniform. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Is  it  your  contention  that  when  the  books 
show  a  deficit  there  during  a  period  of  $182,000,000,  the  rnine  owners 
didn't  know  what  they  were  doing,  didn't  know  anything  about  it, 
didn't  know  what  it  represented,  and  what  caused  it? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Senator,  my  point  has  nothing  to  do  with  profits 
or  losses.  What  I  am  interested  in  is  whether  the  variable  costs  are 
in  fact  uniform,  and,  second,  how  large  they  are  with  relation  to  the 
total  costs. 

Actmg  Chairman  King.  When  you  speak  of  variable  costs,  do  you 
mean,  taking  the  industry  now  under  consideration,  the  cost  of  iron 
ore? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  mean  the  additional  costs  which  are  associated 
with  additions  to  output,  which  is  the  variable  costs  as  Dr.  Yntema 
discussed  them  this  morning. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Well,  the  costs  of  operations  vary  Jrom 
day  to  day  and  from  month  to  month  and  from  year  to  year  ji  any 
industry,  don't  they? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Quite  right. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  The  cost  of  your  ore  one  year  may  be 
considerably  different  from  the  costs  of  ore  for  a  preceding  year,  your 
labor  costs  vary.     Those  are  variable,  aren't  they? 

Dr.  deChazeau.' Yes,  sir.^ 

Acting  Chairman  King.  And  there  are  many  factots  incident  to 
the  determiiiation  of  your  outgo  and  your  income  that  are  variable 
market  conditions,  labor  conditions,  cost  of  raw  materials,  and  the 
prices  of  finished  products  all  go  into  the  sum  total  of  your  conditions 
with  a  view  to  ascertaining  just  what  the  situation  is  and  what  the 
condition  of  your  business  is. 

£)r.  deChazeau.  It  is  all  of  those  conditions  which  Dr.  Yntema 
v/as  analyzing,  eliminating  variations  in  price  by  adjusting  to  1938 
conditions. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  are  not  attempting  to  show  that 
those  figures  which  were  given  as  to  the  costs,  losses,  and  so  on,  were 
inaccurate? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  In  no  sense. 


13622        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Yours  is  a  sort  of  scientific  technological 
discussion  of  things  which  the  practical  man  doesn't  know  anything 
about. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  hope  that  that  is  not  true,  Senator. 
Dr.  Kreps.  May  I  point  out,  Senator,  that  this  line  which  sum- 
marizes the  experience  of  United  States  Steel  does  not  extend  below 
slightly  over  4,000,000  tons.  There  is  nothing  in  the  experience  of 
the  Corporation  which  indicates  what  their  fixed  costs  are  ^elow  that 
level.  Therefore,  the  $182,000,000  figure  which  they  arrive  at  is  a 
guess,  and  a  guess  arrived  at  by  extrapolation.  That  guess  represents 
no  common  sense  experience.  Yet  if  fixed  costs  are  not  relatively 
small,  and  in  particular  if  variable  costs,  instead  of  rising  steeply, 
rise  slowly,  then  the  whole  of  Dr.  Yntema's  further  analysis  falls  by 
the  wayside. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Is  that  testimony  that  you  are  giving  now, 
Doctor,  or  comment  upon  the  testiinony?^ 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  want  to  clarify  the  issue  in  this  case. 
Acting  Chairman  King.  It  may  be  clarified,  but  I  haven't  been 
clarified.     Ptoceed. 

Dr  beChazeau.  Senator,  I  wonder  if  I  could  clarify  the  situation 
by  merely  indicating  this.  If  the  points  in  the  scatter  diagram  from 
which  the  regression  line  was  derived,  were  shifted  slightly  to  the 
right  by  change  in  the  weighting  in  the  latter  years  and  slightly  to  the 
left  in  the  earlier  years,  that  would  have  the  effect  of  requiring  a  fitted 
line  to  those  points  which  would  rise  much  less  rapidly  and  which 
would  cut  the  base  line  at  a  higher  fixed  cost  level.  The  result  would 
be  that  your  figure  for  variable  costs  would  be  less  than  it  is  here 
estimated.  Hence  the  position  of  the  points  in  the  scatter  diagram 
is  very  important  for  the  analysis,  because  as  the  variable  costs  fall 
the  elasticity  of  demand  required  to  make  it  profitable  to  reduce  price 
is  much  less.  That  is  the  only  point  here  considered.  I  am  in  no 
way  challenging  the  figures  used  by  the  Steel  Corporation. 

The  relation  of  recorded  expense  to  volume  of  sales  may  reflect 
managerial  policy  rather  than  actual  cost  and  thereby  exaggerate  the 
apparent  magnitude  of  variable  costs. 

The  arbitrary  character  of  accounting  cost  allocations  with  particu- 
lar reference  to  this  analj^sis  will  be  discussed  before  this  committee 
by  Mr.  Martin  Taitel  and  need  not  be  examined  in  detail  bj^  me. 
The  tendency  to  allocate  costs  co  years  in  which  there  are  receipts 
suflScient  to  cover  them  is  well  known.  To  the  extent  that  these 
charges  are  excessive  in  good  years  and  less  than  "true"  costs  in  bad 
years,  a  bias  will  be  given  to  any  total  cost  function  derived  from  an 
historical  series  which  tends  to  overstate  marginal  with  relation  to 
fixed  costs  and  may  impart  an  erroneous  linearity  to  the  function 
itself.  Possible  examples  are  bonuses  to  executives  associated  with 
with  changes  in  the  level  of  sales;  depreciation  (as  well  as  debits  to 
other  reserves) ;  the  purchase  of  supplies,  materials  for  repair,  and  so 
forth.  The  point  is  important  primarily  because  of  the  size  of  the 
pay  roll  and  the  "other  expense"  items.  These  two  items  consti- 
tuted, during  the  period  analyzed,  almost  84  percent  of  aggregate 
unadjusted  expenses  before  income  taxes,  while  "other  expenses" 
alone  (a  lump  item  without  any  breakdown  in  the  analysis),  accounted 
for  roughly  38  percent  of  the  aggregate.     These  items  so  dominate 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13623 

the  final  results  that  the  con  elusions  can  hardly  be  admitted  without 
more  detailed  analysis  of  the  components  which  went  into  them. 

Probable  error  in  the  adjustment  of  pay  rolls  and  "other  expense" 
to  1938  conditions,  because  of  the  dominating  importance  of  these 
items,  is  sufficient  to  throw  doubt  on  both  the  Imear  character  of  the 
total  cost  fimction  and  the  magnitude  of  the  variable  costs. 

Two  adjustments  were  made  in  pay  roll  data:  Average  hourly 
earnings  were  raised  in  each  year  of  the  period  to  the  average  for 
1938  ($0,902)  aud  the  adjusted  pay  roll  was  then  corrected  for  time 
trend  to  give  effect  to  increasing  productivity.  But  the  first  adjust- 
ment assumes  that  the  same  composition  of  skills  is  used  a't  every  scale 
of  output.  The  proportion  of  skilled  persons  employed,  however,  is 
likely  to  be  greater  at  lower  rates  of  output.  This  may  be  the  reason 
why  the  Corporation  shows  approximately  the  same  average  hourly 
earnings  in  1931  as  in  earlier  years  despite  reduced  rates  in  1931  and 
lower  average  hourly  earnings  m.  1933  than  in  1932  despite  higher  rates. 
The  importance  of  this  factor  cannot  be  ascertained  a  priori.  Since 
most  skilled  workers  in  a  steel  plant  work  on  piecework  with  a  guaran- 
teed hourly  minimum,  the  effect  of  variations  in  the  composition  of 
the  staff  on  average  hourly  earnings  is  modified  by  the  variation  in 
earnings  of  skdled  workers  with  variations  in  output. 

With  reference  to  this  point,  information  which  the  Steel  Corpora- 
tion made  available  just  last  night,  in  which  they  tested  hourly  earn- 
ings with  relation  to  output  over  a  period  from  April  1937  through 
the  current  month  of  39,  indicates  that  there  is  not  much  variation  in 
hourly  earnings  with  changes  in  output.  I  am  not  at  this  time 
prepared  either  to  criticize  or  to  accept  without  reservation  those 
particular  results.  The  method  of  adjustment  employed,  however, 
tends  to  increase  the  slope  of  the  regression  line  and  therefore  to  raise 
the  apparent  variable  costs. 

The  adjustment  for  time  trend  (table  20  and  chart  8  in  "Exhibit 
No.  1416"^)  seems  particularly  unconvincing.  Instead  of  a  single 
line  of  regression,  three  appear  to  be  mdicated.  From  1927  through 
1929,  although  total  pay  roll  remained  about  the  same,  output 
increased,  and,  contrary  to  expectations,  if  variable  costs  were  in  fact 
constant,  the  "trend  in  residuals"  showed  an  increase  in  efficiency  of 
about  15  percent.  From  1930  through  1033,  a  separate  regression 
curve  is  indicated.  Whether  by  reason  of  faulty. wage  adjustment  for 
changes  in  the  composition  of  the  labor  force  or  because  of  techno- 
logical changes,  an  increose  of  efficiency  of  over  10  percent  is  shown. 
Fmally,  a  thu-d  luae  from  1934  through  1937,  while  output  was 
expanding  and  technological  changes  were  being  made,  suggests 
another  gain  of  over  15  percent.  These  gains  were  not  cumulative 
throughout  the  period.  In  the  absence  of  a  break-down  in  pay-roll 
figures  and  of  a  continuous  trend  of  residuals  during  the  period,  the 
conclusion  that  pay-roll  data  conform  to  a  linear  function  is  far  from 
certain.  '  . 

The  adjustment  of  "other  expenses,"  without  knowledge  of  its  com- 
ponent i^ems,  is  even  more  suspect.  Since  its'  magnitude  is  com- 
parable to  that  for  pay  rolls,  the  indicated  increase  in  such  adjusted 
expenses  o\'er  the  period  by  10.47  percent  of  average  implies  that  the 
gains  of  labor-saving  technology  (equivalent  to  14.41  percent  of 
average  pay  roU)  were  largely  nullified  by  such  adjusted  "costs." 

'  Appendix,  pp.  14051  and  14052. 


13624  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  I'OWER 

The  assumptions  that  must  be  made  to  justify  the  weighted  tons 
employed  in  the  analysis  are  so  improbable  as  to  throw  doubt  on  the 
conclusions  derived. 

Co^ts,  for  the  purpose  of  this  analysis  (except  for  nonoperating 
income  and  expense),  cover  all  operations  of  the  Corporation's  sub- 
sidiaries of  whatever  nature  while  sales  are  represented  by  weighted 
tons  of  all  products  shipped  (except  cement  and  certain  liquid  and 
gaseous  coke-oven  byproducts) — somewhat  less  than  the  full  volume 
of  business  represented  in  costs  by  the  amount  of  goods  and  services 
sold  which  are  not  measured  in  tons.  This  conglomerate  is  reduced  to 
a  "homogeneous"  number  of  equivalent  average  mill-cost  units 
called  "weighted  tons"  by  correcting  the  actual  tons  of  each  product 
shipped  in  each  year  by  the  ratio  of  its  average  mill  costs  to  the 
average  mill  costs  of  all  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  over  the 
period  1933-37.  No  data  are  presented  which  would  enable  one  to 
appraise  (a)  the  comparability  of  the  cost  items  included  in  mill  costs 
for  different  products;  (b)  the  representativeness  of  the  average  for 
each  product  in  terms  of  the  range  of  mill  costs  at  a  given  plant  over 
time  or  between  plants  at  a  given  time ;  or  (c)  the  stability  of  the  stand- 
ard adopted,  that  is,  the  average  of  mill, costs  for  all  rolled  and  finished 
products  at  all  plants  over  the  5-year  period. 

Assuming  the  propriety  of  the  mill-cost  averages,  however,  it  is 
necessary  to  assume  also  thr  t  the  ratio  of  the  average  mill  cost  of  each 
product  to  the  average  mill  ;ost  of  all  rolled  and  finished  steel  products 
during  the  sample  period  1  33-37,  was  constant^throughout  the  period 
analysed,  1927-38,  inclusive.  This  is  equivalent  to  an  assumption 
that  no  technological  improvements  took  place  in  one  department  or 
geographic  area  that  did  not  take  place  in  all  departments  or  geo- 
graphic areas.  That  this  was  not  true  as  between  steel  and  nonsteel 
products  may  be  discounted  because  of  the  relatively  small  ratio  of 
weighted  tons  of  nonsteel  products  in  total  weighted  tons.  But  the 
same  can  hardly  be  said  for  hot  and  cold  rolled  light  steel  products 
like  strip,  sheet,  and  tin  plate  which  constituted  a  substantial  and 
apparently  increasing  percentage  of  the  total  tonnage  of  rolled  and 
finished  steel  shipped  during  the  period.  If,  as  seems  likely,  there 
has  been  a  downward  trend  in  the  mill  costs  of  such  light  flat-rolled 
products  relative  to  the  average  of  all  rolled  and  finished  steel  products 
over  the  period  studied,  the  weights  actually  employed  would  reduce 
the  weighted  tons  in  earlier  years. 

The  range  of  actual  adjustment  is  fairly  large — the  spread  of  the 
correction  factors  being  about  10  percent.  Practically  all  of  the  high 
volume  years  are  corrected  downward  while  the  low  volume  years  are 
corrected  upward.  This  results  from  the  relatively  greater  proportion 
of  high^alue  products  like  sheet,  strip,  and  tin  plate  shipped  in  low 
volume  years.  Were  correction  made  for  a  downward  trend  in  mill 
costs  for  flat-rolled  products  the  points  in  the  scatter  diagram  would 
be  shifted  to  the  right  especially  for  the  earlier  years  of  the  period. 
The  net  effect  on  the  slope  or  on  the  linear  character  of  the  regression 
line  cannot  be  determined  for  lack  of  data.  Admittedly,  however,  a 
substantial  change  in  weights  would  be  required  to  make  a  significant 
change  in  results. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13625 

SIGNIFICANCE    OF   THE    COST    STUDY    IN    PRICING    POLICY 

Dr.  deChazeau.  The  cost  relations  traced  in  this  statement  are 
primarily  static  costs  and  cannot  be  used  to  measure  the  change  in 
costs  that  might  be  expected  as  the  Corporation  moves  from  one  level 
of  output  to  another,  the  essential  factor  in  pricing  policy. 

This,  I  think,  is  one  of  the  most  important  criticisms.  By  correcting 
cost  items  to  1938  levels,  it  was  apparently  desired  to  estimate  from 
an  historical  cost  series  the  variation  of  costs  with  changes  in  the  rate 
of  utilization  of  capacity  at  a  given  time.  But  despite  substantial 
changes  in  capacity  over  the  period  studied,  no  correction  was  made 
in  the  weights  (and  therefore  the  output  measurements)  for  variations 
in  the  percent  of  capacity  operated.  The  cost-output  relation  sought 
was  one  applying  to  a  specified  set  of  capacities  while  the  cost  figures 
used  apply  to  different  sets  of  capacities  at  various  times.  Much  of 
the  so-called  variable  costs  in  this  analysis  may  be  found,  on  closer 
examination,  to  reflect  changes  in  capacity  to  produce. 

Although  there  is  reason  to  believe  that  costs  behave  differently 
depending  on  the  direction,  and  the  rate  of  change  in  output  level  as 
well  as  the  preexisting  level  of  output,  no  consideration  was  given  to 
the  effect  of  such  factors.  Suffice  it  to  say  that  there  is  some  internal 
evidence  that  such  was  the  case  with  relation  to  pay  rolls. 

It  was  tacitly  assumed  that  long-run  and  short-run  costs  for  a  given 
output  are  the  same,  that  is,  that  adaptation  takes  place  at  an  ignite 
rate.  This  result,  of  course,  is  implicit  in  the  use  of  annual  rather  than 
montlily  or  quarterly  data.  The  use  of  annual  data,  undoubtedly  was 
forced  on  the  Corporation  by  the  character  of  the  cost  information 
available. 

The  cost  curve  finally  developed  can  be  admitted  as  a  limitation  on 
pricing  policy  only  on  assumptions  which  the  industry  has  rightfully 
denied  and  which  falsify  the  dynamic  character  of  costs. 

The  procedure  employed  in  this  study  is  most  appropriate  for  a 
single  plant  producing  a  single  product.  For  many  plants  producing 
a  wide  variety  of  products,  having  no  inherent  homogeneity,  it  can 
provide  only  the  roughest  kind  of  approximation  at  best  and  it  is 
downright  misleading  at  worst. 

The  steel  industry  has  long  taken  the  position  (and  rightly  so  in  my 
judgment)  that — 

(a)  Costs  are  not  comparable  between  plants  and  areas  since  they 
vary  not  only  with  the  prices  of  the  factors  but  also  with  the  com- 
bination of  products  manufactured. 

(b)  Cost  even  for  a  given  product  at  a  given  mill  will  vary  from  time 
to  time  with  the  combination  of  specifications  rolled. 

(c)  The  steel  industry  produces  a  multitude  of  special  tailor-made 
steel  products  with  widely  diverse  costs. 

We  are  now  asked  to  believe  that  an  analysis  of  the  total  historical 
expenses  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  covering  some  50,000 
steel  products  and  a  multiple  of  nonsteel  products  and  services  ranging 
from  cement,  coal,  and  iron  ore  to  byproducts,  transportation  services 
and  construction,  may  be  assumed  to  represent  the  cost  situation  that 
confronts  the  Corporation  in  making  a  price  for  a  given  steel  product. 


13626        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

At  least  I  take  it  this  is  the  imphcation  of  Dr.  Yntema's  remarks. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  would  expect,  would  you  not,  in  fixing 
the  prices  for  their  various  commodities,  that  they  would  take  into 
account  the  general  activities  in  which  they  are  engaged? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Quite. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  It  would  be  impossible  to  segregate  one 
little  strand,  so  to  speak,  of  the  great  fabric  and  say  the  cost  for  that 
little  one  strand  out  of  perhaps  thousands  of  strands  shall  be  so  and  so. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  right. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  have  to  take  into  account  the  entire 
pattern. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  right. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  And  you  have  to  take  into  account  the 
cost  of  the  ore,  the  cost  of  sliipping  it,  you  have, to  take  into  account 
the  repair  to  the  plants,  the  labor  costs  which  change  from  day  to  day 
and  from  month  to  month,  the  fluctuations  of  the  market,  the  changes 
in  demand,  and  a  multitude  of  factors  which  every  businessman  re- 
luctantly or  otherwise  is  compelled  to  meet  and  to  adjust  himself  and 
adapt  himself  and  his  business  to  those  changing  conditions. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  right.  I  did  assume,  however.  Senator, 
that  Dr.  Yntema's  remarks  bad  reference  to  pricing  policy.  If  they 
have  merely  reference  to  the  fact  that  the  Corporation  makes  losses, 
at  certain  levels  of  output,  at  certain  levels  of  price,  that  is  a  different 
matter  and  restricts  its  significance  considerably,  but  with  relation  to 
prices  it  seems  to  me  that  one  must  of  necessity  consider  these  other 
factors. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  do  not  contend,  do  you,  that  every 
business,  whether  it  is  steel  or  the  grocery  business,  is  going  to  have 
profits  entirely  and  in  determining  year  in  and  year  out  the  business 
which  he  is  conducting  and  the  prices  which  he  shall  charge  and  all 
factors,  he  has  got  to  take  into  account  losses  as  well  as  gains,  good 
years  as  well  as  bad  years. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Dark  days  as  well  as  sunshiny  days. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  should  agree  that  he  must  take  those  uiings  into 
consideration. 

Sinc6  the  location  of  the  points  in  the  scatter  diagrams  depends  on 
the  number  of  weighted  tons  shipped  in  each  year  (i.  e.,  the  weight 
accorded  the  actual  tons  of  each  product  shipped)  and  the  location 
of  these  points  determines  the  regression  line  (and,  therefore,  the 
character  of  variable  costs  and  the  relative  magnitude  of  such  costs), 
it  must  be  assumed  that  the  ratio  of  fixed  to  variable  costs  for  the 
average  of  all  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  is  not  only  charac- 
teristic for  each  of  them  but  also  characteristic  for  all  other  goods  and 
services  supplied  by  the  Corporation.  But  this  is  absurd.  What  are 
variable  and  what  are  overhead  costs  for  a  particular  product  at  a 
particular  time  depend  on  the  alternatives  available  to  management. 
An  integrated  plant  Las  capacity  to  roll  a  large  variety  of  steel  products 
and  a  large  proportion  of  the  costs  of  any  one  is  common  to  the  rest  in 
the  rolling  and  finishing  operations  and  especially  in  prior  processes 
such  as  steel-making  and  pig-iron  furnaces.  \Vlien  the  rate  of  utili- 
zation of  capacity  falls,  it  does  not  fall  uniformly  for  all  products  and 
all  departments;  and  no  matter  how  low  it  may  fall  for  the  plant  as  a 
whole,  there  are  technological  obstacles  to  reduction  in  some  depart- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13627 

ments  below  the  minimum  capacity  of  operating  units  (e.  g.,  blast 
furnaces).  The  additional  costs  of  rolling  or  processing  a  particular 
product  or  a  particular  specification  of  a  product  will  vary  widely  at  a 
given  plant  and  between  plants  depending  on  such  factors  as  level  of 
output,  combination  of  products  and  specifications,  rate  of  change  in 
output,  and  so  forth.  In  other  words,  at  a  given  time,  practically 
all  costs  may  be  overhead  so  far  as  a  given  product  is  concerned. 

Wliy  doesn  't  this  condition,  the  real  scope  for  managerial  discretion 
in  the  allocation  of  existing  business  to  obtain  lowest  costs,  reveal  itself 
.  in  the  cost  analysis  under  consideration?  The  use  of  an  average,  even 
a  weighted  average,  of  all  goods  and  services  sold  by  the  Corporation, 
together  with  total  expenses,  is  the  obvious  reason.  A  very  wide 
diversity  in  the  cost  characteristics  for  individual  products  may  be 
completely  compensated  in  the  over-all  picture.  In  other  words, 
the  behavior  of  the  aggregate  bears  no  necessary  relation  to  that  of 
any  one  of  its  parts,  and  therefore  its  significance  for  the  pricing  of 
any  given  product  is  indeterminate.  Together  with  limitations  on 
the  validity  of  conclusions  previously  outlined,  this  means  that  the 
use  of  such  a  cost'  analysis  as  a  criterion  for  or  a  justification  of  pricing 
policy  cannot  be  accepted. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  Mr.  Chairman,  may  I  interrupt  at  this  point? 
I  haven't  the  faintest  idea  what  you  have  been  talking  about  here. 
Let  me  go  back  for  just  a  minute  and  see  if  I  can  see  the  points  that 
you  have  covered.  I  thought  I  knew  something  about  this  too. 
First  of  all,  you  say  that  where  you  have  a  wide  variety  of  products, 
a  wide  scattering  of  plants,  the  over-alL  pictuje  is  necessarily  confus- 
ing, that  you  could  make  a  detailed  analysis  for  a  given  plant  ^nd  a 
given  product  with  far  more  certainty  than  you  can  make  an  overall 
analysis  for  the  Steel  Corporation.     Is  that  correct? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes. 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  Now,  then,  no  one  quarrels  with  that,  least  of  all, 
I  presume,  Mr.  Yntema.  Then  you  go  ahead  and  you  say  that  it 
follows  from  this  that  you  .can't  draw  any  conclusions  from  average 
price  relationships  or  more  particularly  from  aggregate  cost  relation- 
ships to  aggregate  production  relationships.  It  is  necessary,  is  it  not, 
for  a  business  enterprise  that  is  making  a  sensible  approach  to  a 
question  such  as  the  question  that  is  raised  here  as  to  general  pricing 
policy,  to  arrive  at  what  you  have  described  as  a  rough  approxima- 
tion of  what  those  over-all  relationships  are.  That  would  be  true, 
would  it  not? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes;  I  should  say  so. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  Do  you  know  of  any  work  which  has  been  dqne  in 
the  field  of  merging  unlike  products  and  costs  in  unlike  plants  which 
is  a  more  satisfactory  method  of  arriving  at  that  necessary  approxima- 
tion than  the  job  that  has  been  done  here? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  No 

Mr.  HiNRicHS  (interposing).  Are  you  criticizing  this  as  a  defective 
utilization  of  methods  which  have  been  developed  in  recent  years? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  No.  I  am  interested  in  whether  the  method  as 
applied  to  the  entire  Steel  Corporation,  deriving  your  relation  of  vari- 
able cost  to  fixed  cost  from  an  historical  price  series,  will  in  fact  indicate 
the  extent  of  the  fixed  cost  with  relation  to  the  variable  cost,  which  is  a 
factor  of  importance,  it  seems  to  me,  in' the  pricing  of  the  steel  product. 

124491— 41— pt.  26 4 


13&28       CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

What  I  am  critizicing  is  whether  any  such  development  will  in  fact 
show  you  what  that  proper  relationship  is. 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  That  is,  your  conclusion  would  be  that  the  relation- 
ships would  be  better  arrived  at  through  an  intimate  understanding 
of  price  relationships  in  a  given  plant  for  a  given  product  and  through 
a  process  of  deductive  economic  reasoning  rather  than  through  a 
statistical  approach. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Or  a  statistical  analysis  of  the  operations  of  that 
plant  rather  than  a  statistical  analysis  of  the  operations  of  the  Steel 
Corporation.  Now  I  appreciate  the  limitations  on  Dr.  Yntema's 
work,  which  he  himself  pointed  out,  that  he  couldn't  take  an  indi- 
vidual plant  and  make  such  an  analysis.  I  believe,  however,  that  the 
committee  is  interested  in  this  study  as  it  affects  the  question  of 
price  flexibility  or  possible  price  flexibility  in  the  industry  as  a  whole. 
It  is  from  that  point  of  view  that  I  am  criticizing. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHs.  That  is,  as  I  understand  not  only  what  you  are  say- 
ing in  this  paragraph,  but  in  others,  there  are  certain  points  at  which 
elements  that  were  not  taken  into  account  by  Dr.  Yntema,  in  your 
judgment,  have  given  a  less  deep  curve  than  the  one  that  we  had,  as  for 
example  in  the  general  characteristic  of  carrying  in  the  years  of  good 
business  a  higher  proportion  of  costs  than  are  charged  in  years  of  bad 
business? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHs.  I  think  there  are  other  points  where  you  similarly 
have  questioned,  out  of  your  experience,  the  precise  steepness  of  the 
curve.  Now  in  this  connection  what  you  are  questioning  is  the  prob- 
able error  in  the  final  result  that  comes  out  when  one  is  using  aggre- 
gates. What  you  are  saying  essentially  is  a  thing  which  Dr.  Yntema 
would  agree  with  you  in,  I  presume? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  hope. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHs.  He  would  certainly  be  wiUing  to  give  you  the  prob- 
able error  of  his  line  of  regression,  to  go  technical,  and  what  you  are 
saying  is  that  that  line  or  that  $182,000,000  can  in  no  sense  of  the  word 
be  regarded  as  an  absolutely  fixed  established  sum,  but  that  in  the  very 
materials  we  are  working  with  it  is  at  best  $182,000,000  more  or  less, 
and  the  more  or  less  may  be  very  large. 

The  second  thing  that  you  are  saying  is  that  the  evidence  would  be 
more  conclusive  if  it  were  substantiated  out  of  a  more  particular 
analysis  of  the  cost  operations  in  a  particular  plant  engaged  in  making 
a  specific  product  and  that  the  more  one  refines  the  product  the  less 
statistical  juggling  one  has  to  engage  in,  and  the  more  accurate  one's 
final  conclusions;  is  that  correct? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes;  but  may  I  emphasize  the  importance  of  it? 
Let  me  repeat.  If  this  cost  analysis  is  taken  as  not  merely  representa- 
tive of  the  costs  of  the  Steel  Corporation,  which  incidentaUy  is  an  im- 
portant factor  in  the  industry,  but  as  representative  of  steel  costs 
generally  (i.  e.,  with  relation  to  the  size  of  variable  costs  contrasted 
to  fixed  costs),  the  possibilities  of  price  variation,  of  price  reductions 
in  this  industry,  are  practically  insignificant  and  discussions  of  demand 
elasticity  are  highly  academic.  It  is  true  that  Professor  Yntema,  for 
his  analysis,  after  deriving  a  figure  of  0.3  to  0.4,  assumes  1.0  as  the 
elasticity  of  demand  for  steel. 

It  wouldn't  have  made  much  difference  if  he  had  assumed  2.0  or 
even  3.0;  the  result  would  be  the  same,  although  the  magnitude  of  the 


CX)NCENTtlATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13629 

results  would  be  altered.  Therefore,  it  seems  to  me  that  before  one 
can  accept  such  a  presentation  of  the  costs  as  being  the  actual  relation 
of  variable  to  fixed  costs,  one  must  know  a  little  bit  more  than  one  does 
at  the  moment. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Dr.  deChazeau,  I  am  not  a  professor  nor  a 
doctor  nor  a  technologist,  but  I  have  some  little  practical  appreciation 
of  the  practical  problems  of  life.  I  confess  that  I  am  not  very  clear 
as  to  what  you  are  trying  to  present  for  the  consideration  of  the  com- 
mittee, but  in  order  to  bring  it  down  to  a  concrete  situation,  let  me 
give  you — so  that  I  may  understand  whether  I  understand  you,  and 
whether  the  matter  which  we  are  discussing  is  susceptible  of  concrete 
presentation,  and  presentation  such  as  the  ordinary  man  would  imder- 
stand — a  case  of  this  character.  How  w®uld  you,  if  you  were  running 
the  Corporation,  fix  your  cost  sheets  and  make  your  report  in  order  to 
determine  these-  variables  and  ponderables  and  imponderables,  and 
tangibles  and  intangibles  which  have  been  thrown  at  us  here  with 
great  ability? 

I  have  in  mind  a  corporation  owning  some  mining  properties.  It 
attempted  to  work  them  and  failed;  costs  were  too  great;  it  found  that 
it  had  to  "build  a  railroad;  it  had  to  ascertain  the  costs  of  that  railroad 
and  its  operation,  and  it  had  to  build  smelters.  Those  smelters  didn't 
always  function  properly;  many  of  them  had  to  be  changed;  new 
processes,  technological  processes  in  the  working  out  of  orders  were 
developed,  so  that  a  proposition  which  started  out  with  the  expecta- 
tion of  costing  only  a  few  million,  perhaps  cost  $75,000,000  before  they 
could  make  any  profit  at  all. 

Then  in  determining  what  their  profits  and  their  losses  were",  they 
had  to  take  into  account  the  costs  of  operating  the  ming.  That  hdd 
to  be  changed.  Then,  they  had  to  take  into  account  the  cost  of  re- 
moving the  dirt  and  that  cost  a  great  deal.  Wages  changed.  Then 
came  the  various  acts  of  Congress  under  which  their  taxes  were  in- 
creased. Then  came  the  question  of  depletion,  difficulty  in  deter- 
mining just  what  to  allocate  for  depletion,  what  claims  should  be  made 
by  reasonable  depletion.  There  were  variables  there,  variables  tiiat 
iranged  many  percent  because  some  of  the  scientific  men  said  you  could 
allow  only  so  much  for  depletion,  and  others  insisted  that  in  view  of 
the  fact  that  they  were  taking  out  the  ore  that  capital  was  being 
depleted. 

Then  there  were  the  costs  of  the  railroad  and  then  the  cost  of  the 
smelters,  and  the  wages  differing;  all  those  things;  they  had  a  nimiber 
of  integrated  organizations  all  concentrating,  though,  m  the  final  result 
at. the  end  of  the  year  when  they  had  to  write  the  balance  shept,  all 
those  costs  and  expenses  and  losses  and  profits  were  found  there  in 
that  balance  sheet.  How  would  you  determine  what  to  allocate  to 
the  operation  of  the  mine,  what  to  determine  for  the  smelter,  the  rail- 
road, and  so  on?  How  are  you  going  to  do  it?  Is  not  this  a  practical 
thing  at  the  end  of  the  year,  the  corporation  says,  "We  have  expended 
$20,000,000;  we  have  received  $19,000,000.  We  have  a  deficit  there 
of  $1,000,000."  How  are  you  going  to  allocate  that?  Would  you  say 
they  charged  too  much  for  the  removal  of  the  overhead,  they  charged 
too  much  for  depletion;  they  got  too  large  a  credit  there  and  too  large 
a  loss  there?  The  company  lost  it  or  made  it,  and  the  balance  sheet 
showed  everything  they  received -and  everything  they  expended  for 
the  year,  would  not  that  be  an  honest  balance  sheet? 


13G30  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  I'OWEK 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Quite  an  honest  balance  sheet. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Wouldn't  that  be  the  practical  way  that  a 
practical  man  would  deal  with  his  business  affairs? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  know  that  it  is  bad  form  for  one  being  asked  a 
question  to  reply  with  one,  but  I  wonder  if  you  considered  what  ele- 
ments in  that  cost  situation  would  be  necessary  elements  for  you  if 
you  were  fixing  a  price? 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Well,  if  I  were  fixing  a  price,  as  they  were, 
upon  their  cost  and  determining  what  their  price  should  be,  I  would 
take  into  account  all  of  the  things  that  I  had  expended  in  order  to 
make  the  copper,  though  part  of  it  was  the  railroad,  part  of  it  the 
smelter,  and  part  of  it  was  some  other  commodity;  I  would  take  all 
those  into  account  and  put  them  into  one  balance  to  determine  what 
I  had  paid  out  and  what  my  losses  had  been  or  my  profits. 

Then  I  would  fix  the  price  accordingly. 

Mr.  Feller.  I  wonder  if  I  might  attempt  to  clarify  this?  Am  I 
correct  in  understanding  that  Dr.  Yntema  has  attempted  to  present 
a  formula  under  which  it  is  possible  to  determine  what  the  return  of 
the  Corporation  would  be  from  changing  the  price  of  steel;  in  other 
words  by  examining  the  elasticity  of  demand,  the  variation  in  demand 
which  results  from  the  changes  in  price,  and  by  examining  the  costs 
of  the  Corporation  as  they  appear  on  their  books,  he  has  attempted 
to  produce  a  formula  which  will  tell  the  Steel  Corporation  or  perhaps 
the  industry  as  a  whole  what  sort  of  price  changes  to  make  in  order 
to  make  more  money  or  in  order  to  lose  less? 

Now  that  is  a  highly  practical  task  and  if  the  task  succeeds  Dr. 
Yntema  should  receive  the  collective  thanks  and  esteem  of  the  steel 
industry  and  a  very  substantial  reward.  Now  as  I  understand  it, 
Dr.  deChazeau  is  inquiring  into  the  method  of  the  constru'?tion  of 
that  formula.  Now  again  I  understand  one  of  the  critical  points  in 
the  construction  of  that  formula  is  in  distinguishing  between  those 
costs  which  are  fixed,  which  do  not  vary  with  the  rate  of  operation, 
and  those  costs  which  are  variable,  those  costl  ..hich  change  as  you 
produce  more  or  less  steel. 

Now  may  I  go  on  and  state  my  understanding? 

Acting  Chahman  King.  Aren't  you  assuming,  that  there  is  a  datum 
line,  no  change  in  certain  activities? 

Mr.  Feller.  Exactly,  Senator. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Every  day. 

Mr.  Feller.  What  Dr.  Yntema  started  out  to  do,  was  to  try  to 
determine  those  costs  which  would  be  there  if  the  Steel  Corporation 
produced  only  1  ton  of  steel.  In  other  words,  the  very  rock  bottom 
of  cost.  Now  the  way  he  did  that,  as  I  understand  it,  subject  to  cor- 
rection by  Dr.  Yntema,  was  to  put  down  on  a  diagram  the  costs,  to 
put  a  diagram  which  indicates  on  the  bottom  the  tons  shipped  by  the 
Steel  Corpori\tion;  on  the  side  the  total  cost  of  the  Steel  Corporation; 
to  put  down  on  that  diagram  a  series  of  dots;  each  dot  indicating  the 
particular  rcj^ults  for  a  given  year.  Then  he  took  a  pencil  and  drew 
a  line  through  those  dots.  Then  he  extended  the  line  toward  the 
bottom  and  toward  the  top  and  where  that  line  hit  the  chart  he  said, 
"Those  are  the  fixed  costs,"  and  he  said  thoy  are  $182,000,000,  and 
when  Dr.  Yntema  comes  back  on  the  stand  I  should  like  to  ask  liim 
whether  anyone  in  the  Steel  Corporation  had  ever  heard  of  that 
$1 82,000,000  before  he  produced  this  study. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13631 

Now  I  understand  that  that  is  the  situation,  the  issue  before  the 
committee. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  am  afraid  when  professors  disagree  and 
lawyers  and  so  on,  we  will  not  reach  any  agreement.  I  am  going  to 
interrupt  the  proceedings  for  a  moment. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Since  the  points  which  have  been  raised  pro  and 
con  at  this  time  will  probably  be  discussed  with  Dr.  Yntema,  I  think 
it  will  be  unnecessary  for  me  to  say  any  more  at  the  moment. 

If  the  contentions  of  the  Corporation  with  regard  to  cost  and  demand 
are  admitted,  one  is  forced  to  conclude  that  from  any  break-even 
point  a  price  reduction  will  bring  losses  and  an  upward  price  movement 
will  bring  continuous  and  increasing  profits. 

Briefly,  it  is  the  contention  of  the  Corporation  that  total  costs  are 
linear  and  relatively  steep,  that  variable  costs  are  constant,  and  rela- 
tively large,  and  that  a  demand  elasticity  as  great  as  unity  is  in  excess 
of  anytliing  for  which  the  industry  may  hope.  The  Corporation  con- 
cerns itself  exclusively  with  results  which  might  be  expected  with  a 
price  reduction.  But  demand  elasticity  is  equally  applicable  to  price 
increases  with  a  corresponding  decline  in  volume.  On  the  assumption 
that  costs  vary  by  a  fixed  amount  per  unit  of  putput  (i.  e.,  that  the 
cost  function  is  a  straight  line)  and  that  demand  elasticity  is  unity 
(i.  e.,  that  the  total  sum  expended  for  steel  is  not  affected  by  a  change 
in  price),  it  is  apparent  that  it  would  be  increasingly  profitable  to 
raise  prices,  disastrous  to  lower  them;  and  that  this  situation  is  en- 
hanced if  demand  is  less  elastic  than  unity  (i.  e.,  that  a  larger  total 
sum  is  expended  on  steel  at  a  high  than  at  a  low  price).  The  theo- 
retical monopoly  price  would  be  at  a  point  which  allowed  the  sale  of 
a  single  ton. 

That  this  monopoly  price  would  ever  be  attained  or  approached  Is 
of  course  absurd.  Elasticity  of  the  curve  in  the  vicinity  of  the  break- 
even point  is  no  indication  of  its  elasticity  beyond  the  range  of  observed 
price  variations  (a  limitation  of  great  importance,  incidentally,  on  Dr. 
Yntema's  demand  analysis).  Price  increases  are- checked  by  the  bar- 
gaining power  of  large  buyers  (some  of  which  are  capable  of  producing 
steel  for  their  own  requirements),  by  the  potential  substitution  of 
other  products,  by  the  competition  of  other  steel  companies  suffering 
from  underutilization  of  capacity,  by  the  force  of  public  opinion  in- 
cluding the  threat  of  Government  intervention,  and  so  forth. 

The  point  is  made  merely  to  illustrate  the  inherent  pressure  toward 
higher  prices  in  the  industry  if  the  cost  analysis  of  the  corporation 
be  accepted  either  as  characteristic  for  itself  or  for  tlie  industry.  If, 
as  has  been  contended,  a  price  cut  on  important  business  by  any  mem- 
ber of  the  industry  will  be  met  immediately  by  his  rivals  whether  the 
price  reduction  is  published  or  not  published,  the  result  is  inevitable- 
all  sellers  are  worse  off  than  before.  On  the  other  hand,  any  price 
increase  that  can  be  made  uniform  throughout  the  industry,  and 
maintained,  will  result  in  gains  for  all.  Accepting  the  cost  data  as 
accurate,  it  is  merely  academic  to  consider  whether  price  elasticity  of 
demand  for  steel  is  0.5,  1.0,  2.0  or  even  3.0.  The  question  is  inconse- 
quential, for  whatever  the  value  of  price  elasticity  within  this  range 
the  result  would  be  altered  only  in  degree.  An  elasticity  far  beyond 
that  contemplated  by  any  student  of  the  problem  would  be  required 
to  make  a  policy  of  price  reduction  profitable. 


13632  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

UNITED  STATKS  STEEL  CORPORATION'S  ANALYSIS  OF  DEMAND  FOR  STEEL 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  turn  from  a  consideration  of  the  cost  study  to 
the  study  of  demand.  The  object  of  Dr.  Yntema's  study  of  demand 
is  exceedingly  narrow  and  its  limitations  must  be  borne  in  mind, 
especially  in  any  attempt  to  evaluate  its  significance,  either  as  a  guide 
to  industry  pricmg  policy  or  as  an  indication  of  the  relative  desirability 
or  possibility  of  price  changes  from  a  social  point  of  view.  The  price 
elasticity  of  demand  for  steel,  which  it  purports  to  measure  over  the 
period  1919-38,  is  defined  as  the  percentage  change  in  the  quantity 
of  steel  that  would  have  been  sold  in  a  given  year  had  the  average  level 
of  steel  prices  in  that  year  been  higher  or  lower  than  it  actually  was 
by  a  certain  percentage  but  everything  else  had  been  the  same.  It 
is  this  last  qualification  which  limits  both  the  scope  of  the  question 
and  the  significance  of  the  conclusion. 

I  wish  to  concern  myself  with  three  broad  issues;  namely,  certain 
technical  criticisms  of  the  measure  of  price  elasticity  of  demand  for 
steel  derived,  the  significance  of  such  a  concept  of  demand  for  indus- 
trial pricing  policies,  the  social  problem  raised  by  this  analysis. 

With  regard  to  the  first  issue,  I  conclude  that  the  method  and  data 
employed  have  the  net  effect  of  reducing  the  apparent  short-run 
price  elasticity  of  the  demand  for  steel.  I  should  point  out  here  that 
since  the  time  is  limited  and  since  technical  issues  will  be  analyzed  in 
great  detail  by  Dr.  Bean,  and  especially  because  such  suggestions  as  I 
have  would,  in  my  judgment,  make  no  substantial  change  in  the  result, 
I  shall  pass  over  these  points  ve^^  briefly  and  not  read  my  entire 
manuscript. 

In  later  analyses,  a  demand  elasticity  of  unity  (substantially  greater 
than  that  of  0.3  or  0.4  derived  from  this  study)  is  used  by  Dr.  Yntema 
on  general  thigoretical  grounds,  there  is  reason  to  believe  that  the  short- 
run  price  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  is  relatively  low.  A  correction 
therefore  for  the  technical  defects  to  be  noted  by  me  would  probably 
not  make  any  important  change  in  the  ultimate  conclusion.  This 
is  the  more  certain  if  the  cost  analysis  be  accepted.  The  correlation 
technique,  however,  is  no  more  than  a  mathematical  grist  mill  and 
the  significance  of  the  results  obtained  cannot  be  greater  than  the 
meaningfulness  of  the  basic  data  which  are  subjected  to  this  method 
of  treatment. 

The  measure  of  quantity  sold  is  an  ambiguous  and  changing  aggre- 
gate, the  use  of  which  tends  to  reduce  elasticity  to  a  minimum. 

Dr.  Yntema  pointed  this  out  himself,  and  after  explaining  that 
individual  steel  products  do  not  have  the  same  economic  importance 
per  unit  of  weight,  they  are  not  subject  to  the  same  demand  conditions, 
and  their  relative  character  and  importance  changes  from  year  to 
year,  he  proceeded  to  use  an  aggregate  of  such  items. 

Now  the  larger  the  aggregate  employed  and  the  more  diverse  the 
products  included  in  if,  the  smaller  must  be  the  apparent  price  elas- 
ticity of  demand  on  the  assumption  that  other  things  are  equal. 
Although  substitution  of  steel  for  other  products  and  vice  versa  is 
likely  to  be  very  small  in  the  short  run,  even  for  individual  products, 
it  is  negligible  for  steel  as  a  whole. 

The  measure  of  price  change  adopted  tends  to  minimize  the  import- 
ance of  price  in  accounting  for  changes  in  volume. 


CONCENTHIATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13633 

Dr.  Ynoema  used  the  Iron  Age  finished  steel  composite,  which  is 
an  arithmetic  average  of  the  published  prices  of  eight  steel  products  at 
Pittsburgh.  As  he  pointed  out  this  morning,  he  also  ran  a  later  corre- 
lation in  which  he  used  average  mill  nets  for  the  Corporation  and 
found  that  no  substantial  change  took  place.  It  is  important  to  note, 
however,  that  the  more  inflexible  the  measure  of  prioe  change  adopted 
(not  so  much  in  number  of  changes  as  in  amount  of  change),  the 
greater  the  weight  which  will  be  given  to  factors  other  than  price  in 
accounting  for  changes  in  the  volume  of  sales.  For  example,  had  there 
been  no  change  whatever  in  the  measure  of  price,  the  correlation 
technique  perforce  would  attribute  all  changes  in  volume  of  sales  to 
factors  other  than  price. 

With  relation  to  -the  use  oi  mill  nets  I  merely  add  this  point.  I 
accept  Dt  Yntema's  statement  that  the  use  of  the  average  mill  nets 
would  not  affect  the  results  substantially.  I  criticize  primarily  the  use 
of  an  average  which,  unless  it  can  be  assumed  that  all  prices  move 
together,  will  cover  up  the  extent  of  the  price  change  as  it  may  affect 
any  given  product,  and  therefore  any  given  increase  in  demand.  For 
example,  a  break  in  sheet  and  strip  prices  around  the  middle  of  October 
1939,  first  of  $4  a  ton,  followed  later  by  $2  a  ton,  which  did  not  rep- 
resent a  general  reduction  in  price  of  steel  at  that  time,  might  well 
have  affected  an  increase  in  the  demand  for  those  steel  products,  but 
mill  net,  the  average  mill  net  for  all  products,  would  show  a  reduction 
which  was  much  less  than  that  for  those  particular  products. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Well,  is  there  any  relation  between  a 
reduction  in  price  and  general  consumption?  I  know  of  many  in- 
stances in  which  the  reduction  price  of  metal  didn't  make  any  material 
increase  in  the  consumptive  demands.  Does  it  follow  as  a  rule  that 
when  you  reduce  the  price  of  a  commodity  there  will  be  a  great 
increase  in  its  consumption? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  It  does  not  always  foUow  as  a  rule;  no. 
Acting  Chairman  King.  The  exceptions  are  very  numerous,  aren't 
they? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Very  numerous. 

The  use  of  annual  rather  than  monthly  or  quarterly  data  eliminates 
the  importance  of  the  rate  of  price  change  as  an  independent  variable 
and,  therefore,  makes  impossible  a  consideration  of  the  timing  of 
price  change.  Steel  prices  are  usually  announced  on  a  quarterly  basis 
although  actual  prices,  through  concessions,  may  be  made  from  day  to 
day.  Annual  data  eliminate  seasonal  factors  in  demand  and  reduce 
the  importance  of  speculative  buying.  But  seasonal  factors  are  more 
properly  eliminated  statistically  to  leave,  in  the  monthly  or  quarterly 
figures,  sales  variations  which  may  reflect  price  change.  And  specula- 
tive buying  is  an  integral  part  of  the  demand  for  steel  of  admitted 
importance  of  the  steel  industry  in  the  determination  of  price  policy, 
and  of  great  social  importance  as  well,  whenever  there  is  less  than  full 
use  of  resources  in  the  ecoiiomy.  To  nullify  this  speculative  factor 
in  demand  is  to  preclude  an  analysis  of  the  timing  of  price  change  with 
respect  to  consumer  expectations  and  the  demand  for  durable  goods, 
producers'  expectations  and  the  decision  to  invest,  and  changes  in  th6 
prices  of  substitute  and  complementary  goods. 

By  his  selection  of  data,  therefore.  Dr.  Yntema  is  precluded  from 
giving  effect  to  the  following  factors,  crucial  in  the  concept  of  price 
elasticity  of  demand : 


13634       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(1)  The  ratio  of  steel  product  prices  to  the  prices  of  substitute 
materials  or  products  in  the  manufacture  of  goods  made  from  steel  or 
in  consumption. 

(2)  The  ratio  of  steel  product  prices  to  the  prices  of  complementary- 
goods  used  in  the  manufacture  of  goods  made  from  steel. 

(3)  The  rate  of  actual  price  change  for  steel  products  with  regard 
to  the  demand  for  those  products. 

(4)  The  timing  of  price  change  with  regard  primarily  to  the  timing 
of  investment. 

A  fourth  point  which  I  note  here  I  sliall  pass  over  immediately. 
Dr.  Yntema  worked  out  liis  correlation  for  several  relations,  that  is 
one  on  the  basis  of  shipments  and  one  on  the  basis  of  bookings,  and 
so  forth.  I  refer  specifically  to  the  latter.  There  is  no  convincing 
r':^ason  why  Dr.  Yntema  adopts  the  figure  of  0.3  to  0.4  as  a  maxi- 
mum potential  value  of  demand  elasticity,  rather  than  the  figure  0.88 
determined  on  the  basis  of  estimated  steel  bookings.  I  shall  leave 
that  for  Dr.  Yntema  to  discuss. 

SIGNIFICANCE    OF    CONCEPT    OF   DEMAND    FOR    INDUSTRIAL    PRICE 
POLICY 

Dr.  deChazeau.  My  general  conclusion  is  that,  as  a  criterion  of  pric- 
ing policy  for  the  steel  industry  itself,  the  price  elasticity  of  demand 
measured  by  Dr.  Yntema  is  inadequate. 

Three  important  aspects  of  demand  require  separate  analysis  as  a 
basis  for  the  pricing  policy  of  any, seller:  First,  the  cross  elasticity  of 
the  demand,  by  wliich  is  meant  the  percentage  variation  in  quantity 
of  products  sold  by  a  given  seller  with  a  given  percentage  change  in 
his  price  on  the  assumption  that  tiiis  price  is  not  met  immediately 
by  his  rival.  Second,  the  price  elasticity  of  the  market  demand,  and 
third,  shifts  in  the  demand  for  any  product  at  any  given  price.  Dr. 
Yntema  neglects  all  but  the  second,  the  price  elasticity  of  market 
demand. 

There  is  no  error  in  neglecting  cross-elasticity  of  demand,  as  1  have 
defined  it,  for  the  very  obvious  reason  that,  as  has  been  noted  many 
times  before  this  committee,  no  cut  in  price  can  take  place  among 
important  sellers  for  important  business  that  is  not  immediately  met 
by  rivals.  Under  those  conditions,  each  seller  must  of  necessity 
consider,  not  the  cross-elasticity  of  demand,  but  the  elasticity  of  the 
market  demand  in  determining  what  price  is  desirable  for  him. 

An  average  figure  of  price  elasticity  over  the  period  1919  through 
1938  is  almost  certain  to  be  erroneous  as  a  criterion  of  price  elasticity 
of  demand  at  any  given  time. 

The  demand  for  producers'  goods,  either  raw  materials  or  capital 
goods,  is  a  derived  demand.  In  addition  then  to  the  degree  of  sub- 
stitutabiUty  and  the  cost  of  transfer  from  one  material  to  another, 
the  elasticity  of  demahd  for  producers'  goods  at  "any  given  time  is 
affected  by  two  variables.  First,  if  the  prices  of  complementary 
goods  (i.  e.,  labor  and  other  materials)  required  along  with  the^  goods 
in  question  are  constant,  the  price  elasticity  of  demand  for  that 
producei-s'  goods  will  be  low — substantially  less  than  that  for  the 
finished  product  from  which  it  was  derived.  Second,  since  the  pro- 
duction process  is  a  time-consuming  process  (longer  for  capital  goods 
than   fqr  raw   materials),   the   elasticity   of   demand   for   producers' 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13635 

goods  will  vary  with  the  expectations  of  buyers  as  to  the  potential 
business  situation  and  potential  shifts  in  the  demand  for  their  finished 
product  over  a  future  which  varies  in  length  with  that  of  the  pertinent 
production  process. 

Since  steel  is  primarily  a  producers'  good,  the  price  elasticity  of 
market  demand  will  have  two  functional  characteristics,  neither  of 
which  is  given  effect  in  Dr.  Yntema's  study. 

(1)  Price  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  products  is  likely  to  vary 
widelv  with  the  amount  of  price  change. 

Small  price  changes,  the  only  changefe  measured  by  Dr.  Yntema, 
may  have  little  or  no  effect  on  quantities  pm-chased  while  large 
changes  may  cause  substantial  variations.  This  is  perhaps  an  un- 
avoidable defect  of  the  correlation  method  of  estimating  demand  elas- 
ticity from  historical  price  series  where  price  changes  are  small.  It 
was  admitted  as  a  possible  qualification  to  his  analysis  by  Dr.  Yntema 
(see  "Exhibit  No.  1411").  To  my  mind  the  error  is  graver  than  he 
appreciates.  He  analyzes  demand  as  though  it  were  a  continuous 
function  of  price,  that  is,  as  though  increases  of  demand  occurred 
with  very  small  changes  in  the  price.  Even  if  so,  it  is  hazardous  to 
project  demand  elasticity  beyond  the  range  of  observed  price  changes. 
But  the  considerations  already  noted  suggest  that,  for  producers' 
goods,  the  demand  is  more  likely  to  be  a  discontinuous  function  of 
price.  This  means  that  with  a  small  change  in  price,  no  change 
takes  place  in  quantity  sold,  but  with  a  large  change,  you  may  get  a 
substantial  increase  in  output. 

Mr.  HiNRicHs.  What  you  mean  there  is  that  the  increase  in  con- 
sumption with  the  20-percent  reduction  in  price  might  be  more  than 
twice  as  great  as  the  increase  in  consumption  with  the  10-percent 
reduction.  You  don't  mean  that  Dr.  Yntema  has  omitted  any  ob- 
servations but  that  the  changes  in  the  price  of  steel  in  the  past  have 
been  so  narrow  as  to  restrict  this  study  to  the  effect  of  comparatively 
small  changes  in  price? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  perfectly  right.  Please  bear  in  mind  that 
I  am  not  criticizing  Dr.  Yntema  as  a  statisticiaji.  I  have  the  greatest 
admiration  for  Dr.  Yntema's  work.  What  I  am  calling  attention  to 
are  certain  limitations  as  to  the  significance  of  the  demand  elasticity 
as  determined  by  the  correlation  method.     That  is  my  only  objective. 

(2)  Price  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  products  is  likely  to  vary 
substantially  from  one  stage  of  the  business  cycle  to  another,  that  is, 
from  one  level  of  price  for  complementary  goods  and  from  one  level 
of  business  expectations  to  another. 

The  time  of  price  change  and  the  responsiveness  of  the  price  of 
steel  to  other  factors  in  the  total  market  situation  cannot  be  ignored 
without  invalidating  the  measure  of  demand  elasticity  derived.  It 
seems  almost  self-evident  that  no  businessman  could  neglect  with 
impunity  the  importance  of  the  timing  of  his  price  changes.  By  the 
same  token,  any  average  measure  of  demand  elasticity  which  abstracts 
from  it  must  prove  an  erroneous  criterion  of  pricing  policy.  Such  an 
average  demand  elasticity  over  the  period  1919  to  1938  has  been 
derived  here  by  the  correlation  method.  That  is,  actual  changes  in 
sales  were  correlated  with  actual  changes  in  the  finished  composite 
price,  and  the  demand  curve  was  derived  from  it. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  May  I  interrupt  with  a  second  question  on  this 
subiect?     When  you  are  talking  about  the  relationship  between  the 


J  3636        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

changes  in  the  price  of  steel  and  the  use  of  steel  and  pointing  out 
that  steel  is  a  producer's  good,  very  largely,  and  that  the  change  in 
the  price  of  steel  is  only  going  to  effect  demand  significantly  if  it  is 
passed  on  in  the  final  product,  you  are  distinguishing,  are  you  not, 
between  two  different  points  of  view,  with  reference  to  which  this 
problem  of  price  flexibility  might  be  approached.  From  the  business- 
man's approach  as  to  what  he  can  reasonably  expect  to  have  happen 
and  how  he  ought  to  behave  in  ihe  face  of  that,  insofar  as  he  is  en- 
gaged in  making  polic;^  the  fact  that  a  change  in  the  price  of  steel  is 
not  necessarily  passed  on,  is  a  very  important  factor  for  the  consider- 
ation of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  as  a  business  enterprise. 

What  you  are  opening  up  in  that  suggestion  is  the  further  suggestion 
that  there  is  a  very  real  interest  by  the  community  at  large  in  general 
matters  of  pricing  policy,  that  a  change  in  the  price  of  steel  alone 
would  be  likely  to  have  a  very  insignificant  effect,  that  changes  in  the 
price  of  steel  plus  changes  in  the  price  of  other  products  if  reduced 
costs  of  steel  were  fully  passed  on,  might  have  a  very  much  larger 
effect  that  has  been  the  case  in  the  past,  when  very  frequently  those 
changes  in  price  were  not  passed  on  in  a  reduction  in  the  price  of 
finished  goods. 

Is  that  a  correct  interpretation  of  the  limitation  that  you  drew 
earlier  in  your  discussion  there? 

Dr  deChazeau.  That  is  a  point  which  I  planned  to  make. 

Dr.  HiNRicHS.  I'm  sorry. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  You  have  gone  a  little  beyond,  I  thinly,  any  point 
that  I  have  made  as  yet.  My  main  point  here,  if  I  may  interpolate, 
is  merely  this:  That  since  the  demand  for  producers'  goods  is  likely 
to  vary  with  profit  expectations,  and  since  also  insofar  as  steel  is 
a  raw  material  which  may  be  substituted  for  other  materials,  the  cost 
of  transfer  and  substitutability  may  be  involved,  you  might  expect 
two  conclusions;  first,  that  the  demand  elasticity  would  be  very  low 
in  the  short  run  for  a  small  change  in  price,  but  it  might  be  much 
greater  with  a  larger  change  in  price;  and,  second,  that  the  demand 
elasticity  is  likely  to  vary  from  one  stage  of  the  business  cj^cle,  and 
therefore  business  expectations,  to  another  stage. 

That  is  the  onlj^  point  which  I  am  making  here,  if  you  take  a  single 
static — that  is,  "normal" — concept  of  demand  elasticity  throughout 
the  entire  period  of  1919  to  1938,  it  seems  to  me  that  theoretically 
you  must  have  an  erroneous  picture  of  demand  with  reference  to 
potential  price  changes  for  any  given  state  of  facts,  even  though,  as 
an  average,  it  may  have  some  meaning. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  When  your  commodity  perhaps  may  be 
subjected  to  competition  from  abroad,  that  is  a  factor,  tangible  or 
intangible,  affecting  the  question  of  elasticity,  is  that  not  true? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Senator,  I  should  say  it  would  not  affect  the 
(juestion  of  elasticity  but  it  will  affect  the  question  of  what  price  you 
charge. 

Acting  Cliairman  Ivino.  You  relate  elasticitj^  to  prices,  don't  you 
directly  or  indirectly? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes;  but  elasticity  is  a  measure  of  the  variation 
in  the  proportion  of  steel  which  will  be  taken  with  a  given  propor- 
tionate change  in  its  price. 

Noiv,  imports  from  abroad  or  price  competition  from  abroad  may 
have  I  ho  elFert  of  foicing  the  Steel  Corporation  or  forcing  domestic 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13637 

producers  to  reduce  their  prices  irrespective  of  the  elasticity  of 
demand. 

The  assumption  that  other  things  are  equal,  a  necessary  assump- 
tion for  the  derivation  of  a  statistical  measure  of  price  elasticity  from 
a  time  series  by  the  correlation  technique,  is  false  and  vitiates  the 
conclusion  as  a  measure  of  the  effect  of  a  price  change  in  a  dynamic 
situation. 

When  I  say  it  is  false,  I  mean  as  an  actual  market  phenomenon, 
one  can  change  that  assumption  but  it  narrows  the  significance  of 
your  conclusions. 

As  indicated  a  moment  ago,  the  price  elasticity  of  demand  for  a 
steel  product  is  likely  to  vary  from  one  state  of  facts  to  another; 
that  is,  either  within  the  so-called  business  cycle  or  over  longer  periods 
of  time.  More  important  for  pricing  pohcy  than  price  elasticity  at 
any  given  time  are  shifts  in  the  entire  demand  curve  for  the  product. 
That  such  shifts  may  take  place  in  the  absence  of  price  change  or 
despite  a  price  change  for  a  particular  product  does  not  mean  that 
they  may  be  neglected  in  the  determination  of  pricing  pohcy.  Dr. 
Yntema's  analysis  of  price  elasticity  does  neglect  the  impact  of  price 
on  shifts  in  the  demand  curve. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Would  you  explain  more  clearly  what  you  mean  by 
shifts  in  the. demand  curve? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes;  a  shift  in  the  demand  curve  represents  an 
increase  in  the  quantity  that  will  be  taken  at  the  same  price;  that  is, 
a  change  in  the  economic  conditions,  either  by  reason  of  a  change  in 
profit  expectations  or  by  reason  of  a  change  in  the  general  cost  picture, 
which  will  increase  the  demand  for  the  product  without  a  change  in 
its  price;  whereas  demand  elasticity  is  of  necessity  a  measure  of  rela- 
tive changes  in  quantity  to  be  taken,  with  relative  changes  in  price, 
and  therefore  implicitly  assumes  that  the  conditions  remain  the  same. 

Dr.  Kreps.  To  state  what  you  have  to  say  a  little  more  clearly  or 
fully,  Dr.  Yntema's  analysis  assumes  that  at  a  given  price  or  for  an 
average  of  prices  for  steel  products,  the  same  amount  would  be  taken 
throughout  the  period  which  he  covers,  namely,  1929,  1932,  1937,  and 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  right.  That  is,  it  seems  to  me  that  in  the 
use  of  the  demand  elasticity  figure  which  he  has  developed,  which  is 
derived  from  the  study  of  an  historical  series  from  1919  to  1938,  in 
the  use  of  that  curvfe,  he  must  assume  that  irrespective  of  the  changes 
in  conditions,  the  Actual  demand  change  with  relation  to  the  price 
change  would  have  been  the  same  in  any  year. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Do  you  regard  that  as  probably  true  ,to  fact,  that  at 
any  given  price,  the  same  amount  of  steel  could  have  been  sold  both 
m  1929,  1932,  1937,  and  1938,  or  is  that  contrary  to  fkct? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Well,  I  clearly  regard  it  as  erroneous,  as  I  have 
just  stated. 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  Pardon  me,  but  did  you  state  yourself  correctly 
there,  that  the  same  quantity  of  steel  would  be  sold  at  the  same  price 
in  any  one  of  these  years,  or  did  you  mean  to  say  that  Dr.  Yntema's 
analysis  indicates  that  a  10-percent  reduction  from  the  prices  which 
prevailed  in  1932  would  have  tended  to  increase  consumption  in  1932 
by  3  or  4  percent.  That  is,  a  reduction  of  10  percent  from  whatever 
price  prevailed  in  1932  when  they  were  selling  four  and  a  half  million 
tons,  would  have  yielded  another  3  or  4  percent  above  the  four  and 


13638       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

a  half  million  tons.  Similarly,  prices  10  percent  lower  than  those 
which  prevailed  in  1937  would  have  tended  to  produce  10  percent 
greater  consumption  than  the  13,000,000  tons  that  were  sold  in  1937? 
It  was  that  10  percent  related  to  3  percent  that  you  spoke  of  as  being 
constant? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  It  is  the  elasticity  relationship. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  Would  that  be  constant  year  after  year  as  this  is 
presented?  You  didn't  mean  to  say  that  at  $75  a  ton  for  a  given 
product,  the  same  quantity  would  be  sold  in  1932  and  1937? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  No;  because  obviously  he  points  out  the  effect  of 
industrial  conditions  upon  the  total  demands  for  steel  as  being  a  very 
important  factor. 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  Your  point  is  merely  then  that  there  is  logical  reason 
to  believe  that  the  effect  of  the  10  percent  price  reduction  in  one 
phase  of  the  business  cycle  may  be  very  different? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Very  different. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  Than  the  effect  of  a  10  percent  price  reduction  in 
another  phase  of  the  business  cycle? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  my  point. 

Mr.  Feller.  Can  your  point  be  restated  in  this  way,  not  that  Dr. 
Yntema  has  overlooked  the  fact  that  there  are  changes  in  underlying 
business  conditions,  but  that  he  has  derived  the  theoretical  measure 
of  elasticity  which  can  apply  only  if  all  other  things  are  equal,  and 
all  other  things  are  never  equal? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes;  as  I  see  it  for  the  purpose  of  application  of 
the  correlation  technique  to  a  historical  series,  with  the  object  of 
deriving  a  price  elasticity  of  demand,  you  must  assume  that  other 
things  are  equal,  and  he  has  explicitly  made  that  assumption.  I  have 
no  doubt  whatsoever  that  Dr.  Yntema  would  agree  that  conditions 
are  not  equal  from  one  time  to  another. 

Now^  as  he  pointed  out  this  morning,  it  was  his  own  judgment 
that  although  secondary  repercussions  of  price  change  would  inisrease 
demand,  such  a  possible  shift  in  demand  was  far  more  than  compen- 
sated by  his  assumption  of  a  unitary  elasticity  of  demand,  some  three 
times  greater  than  the  0.3  to  0.4  elasticity  which  his  study  indicated. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  don't  quite  understand.  Professor 
[laughter],  how  in  this  changing  world,  in  this  rather  confused  political 
and  economic  and  industrial  situation,  you  can  predicate  any  view 
that  prices  will  be  the  same  tomorrow  or  the  next  day  in  any  industry 
or  in  relation  to  any  product.  I  cannot  conceive  of  a  formula  that 
would  compel  or  produce  or  result  in  a  straight  line,  if  I  may  use  that 
expression,  of  prices  with  respect  to  any  particular  product,  and  if  Dr. 
Yntema  attempted  to  convey  the  idea  that  there  was  a  formula  under 
the  terms  of  which,  in  this  changing  economic  situation,  there  would 
be  a  constancy  of  prices,  I  did  not  understand  it  and  I  would  not 
agree  with  him,  if  that  was  his  view. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Neither  did  I  understand  that  to  be  his  view. 
What  he  was  trying  to  indicate  was  the  cost  situation,  on  the  one  hand, 
and  the  demand  situation,  on  the  other,  which  confronted  the  United 
States  Steel  Corporation  in  making  a  price  or  in  determining  whether 
a  price  reduction  was  desirable. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Well,  the  cost  situation  can  change  as  well 
as  the  demand  can  change,  can  it  not — if  not  there,  at  least  frequently? 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13639 

Dr.  deChazeau.  It  changes  in  a  stable  way,  namely,  that  the 
variable  cost  is  a  constant  and  varies  with  the  output. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Well,  I  wouldn't  agree  with  that. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  hope  not.  [Laughter.]  That  is  what  I  have 
been  trying  to  bring  out. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Well,  I  am  very  glad  that  w-  ehcited  now 
the  proper  interpretation  of  your  observations. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  If  it  could  be  assumed  that  the  economy  was 
operating  at,  or  that  there  was  an  effective  tendency  toward  fiill  use 
of  resources  and  that  prices  were  governed  by  differential  costs,  this 
atomistic  approach  to  the  problem  of  demand  on  the  assumption  that 
other  things  are  equal  would  be  less  fallible.  But  the  larger,  in  terms 
of  employment,  the  industry  under  consideration,  the  more  important 
the  impact  of  its  pricing  policies  on  the  economy,  the  more  character- 
istic the  adoption  of  prices  only  indirectly  related  to  differential 
costs,  and  the  more  widespread  is  unemployment  of  resources,  the 
more  certain  it  becomes  that  other  things  are  not  and  cannot  be 
expected  to  be  equal.  If  other  things  cannot  be  assumed  equal, 
Dr.  Yntema's  analysis  of  price  elasticity  of  demand  cannot  be  con- 
sidered a  criterion  of  desirable  pricing  policy  even  for  the  United 
States  Steel  Corporation. 

Irrespective  of  short-run  inelasticity  in  demand,  prices  of  steel 
products  must  be  adapted  to  the  long-run  development  of  volume 
business  by  consuming  industries. 

In  the  short  period  it  is  probable  that  the  demand  for  most  products 
and  especially  that  for  producers'  goods,  either  raw  materials  or 
capital  goods,  is  relatively  inelastic.  The  short-run  demand  for 
consumers'  goods  tends  to  be  governed  by  habits  of  consumption. 
Among  producers'  goods,  the  substitution  of  one  raw  material  for 
another  is  limited  by  technological  conditions  involving  product 
design,  labor  skills  and  installed  capital  equipment  and  the  demand 
for  any  given  raw  material  is  limited  by  the  prices  which  must  be 
paid  for  complementary  goods,  including  labor.  Substitution  and 
the  development  of  volume  business  in  a  steel  product,  therefore,  is 
probably  a  function  of  long-run  pricing  policies  rather  than  short-run 
and  of  adaptation  of  product  to  consumer  needs  more  than  either. 

The  automobile  industry  illustrates  my  meaning.  Although  at 
any  given  time  in  the  evolution  of  that  industry,  the  price  elasticity 
of  demand  for  steel  products  was  probably  low,  the  development  of 
steel  products,  such  as  sheet  and  strip,  which  could  be  stamped  and 
processed  under  mass  production  conditions,  together  with  a  down- 
ward trend  in  prices  of  these  products,  has  undoubtedly  constituted 
a  major  factor  in  the  growth  of  the  consuming  industry  and  the 
demand  for  steel.  Neither  the  ratio  of  steel  costs  to  total  costs  in 
the  consuming  industry  nor  the  existing  price  elasticity  of  the  demand 
for  automobiles  could  measure  this  potential  demand  for  steel.  (By 
way  of  parentheses,  the  ratio  of  steel  costs  to  retail  price  of  goods 
made  from  steel,  as  used  by  the  Corporation,  understates  the  impor- 
tance of  steel  cost  in  finished  price  since  it  neglects  aU  margins  in 
distribution  commonly  computed  on  a  percentage  basis.  This  is  a 
minor  point,  however,  and  the  cori-eution  perhaps  would  be  small.) 

It  was  the  profit  potentialities  in  a  new  method  of  production 
wicth   were    altered    by   sticb    changes.     To   measure   the   potential 


13640       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

demand  for  steel  by  the  ratio  of  steel  costs  to  total  costs  per  unit  of 
finished  product  on  the  assumption  that  all  other  things  are  equal,  is 
to  violate  the  dynamics  of  demand  and  to  neglect  the  influence  of 
altered  profit  possibilities  on  the  character  of  the  productive  process 
and  consequently  on  investment,  employment  and  purchasing  power. 

What  has  probably  been  true  of  automobiles  may  still  be  true  of 
containers,  housing  and  other  consuming  industries.  The  only  point 
here  stressed  is  that  the  short-run  price  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel 
products,  on  the  assumption  that  other  things  are  equal,  falsifies  the 
character  of  the  demand  for  steel. 

Irrespective  of  short-run  inelasticity  of  demand,  price  policies  for 
steel  products  must  be  integrated  in  time  with  investment  opportuni- 
ties if  a  desirable  volume  of  business  is  to  be  maintained. 

The  demand  for  capital  ^  goods,  for  other  producers'  goods,  that  is, 
raw  materials,  and  even  for  durable  consumers'  goods  varies  primarily 
with  price  and  income  expectations  of  buyers.  Thus  the  pricing  of 
any  durable  goods  is  of  the  utmost  importance  as  it  may  affect  the 
timing  of  purchase.  In  an  economy  in  which  there  is  an  effective 
tendency  toward  full  use  of  resources,  this  shift  in  purchases  over 
time,  rather  than  any  net  increase  in  total  demand  in  the  long  run, 
might  be  expected  to  exhaust  the  possibilities  in  the  timing  of  price 
change.  Even  in  this  state  of  facts,  the  timing 'of  price  change  would 
be  far  from  an  incidental  phase  of  price  poHcy  in  its  tendency  to 
correct  business  cycle  changes  and  maintain  volume  of  sales. 

But  in  the  presence  of  a  large  and  possibly  permanent  volume  of 
unemployment,  proper  price  changes  may  not  merely  shift  an  existing 
demand  in  time,  but,  through  their  impact  on  investment,  employment, 
and  income  in  the  economy  as  a  whole,  they  may  bring  a  net  increase 
in  total  demand.  Thus,  a  price  policy  dictated  by  a  demonstrated 
short-run  inelasticity  of  demand  for  steel — i.  e.,  a  high  price — may 
defeat  the  interests  of  the  industry.. 

Increased  expenditures  on  steel  at  the  higher  price  would  limit 
potential  expenditures  in  other  directions.  These  reduced  expendi- 
tures mean  lower  money  incomes  for  producers  of  other  goods, 
decreased  profit  possibilities  or  increased  losses,  and  consequently 
increased  unemployment.  The  effect  is  likely  to  be  cumulative 
because,  characteristically  in  such  a  state  of  facts,  actual  steel  prices 
exceed  differential  costs  while  investment  by  the  steel  industry  is 
likely  to  be  curtailed.  In  other  words,  hoarding  by  the  steel  industry 
is  more  likely  to  increase  than  to  decrease.  The  net  result  is  a  decrease 
in  the  demand  for  steel. 

To  the  extent  that  the  steel  industry  is  a  price  leader  for  other 
industries,  the  restrictive  effect  on  the  national  income  is  magnified 
and  the  demand  for  steel  is  further  restricted,  That  is,  if  other 
industries  follow  steel  prices,  a  rise  in  steel  prices  bringing  a  higher 

f)rice  in  other  industries,  would  have  the  same  restrictive  and  cumu- 
ative  effect. 

Finally,  as  to  the  social  problem,  if  Dr.  Yntema's  analysis  of  demand 
reflects  faithfully  the  businessman's  criterion  of  desirable  price,  he 
has  dramatized  the  conflict  of  private  and  social  interest  in  pricing 
policy  which  is  the  fundamental  issue  before  the  Temporary  National 
Economic  Committee. 

In  an  economy  in  which  there  is  less  than  full  use  of  resources,  the 
public  interest  in  pricing  pohcies  centers  on  the  impact  of  industrial 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13641 

prices  on  total  employmenc  and  income.  After  Dr.  Laughlin  Currie's 
able  exposition  before  this  committee/  it  is  not  necessary  for  me  to 
explain  how  national  income  is  but  another  aspect  of  total  expendi- 
tures, primarily  by  businessmen,  on  production  and  investment.  But 
a  price  reduction  for  a  given  product  which  merely  increases  expendi- 
tures on  that  product  at  the  expense  of  substitutes  may  have  no  net 
advantage  for  the  economy  as  a  whole.  Indeed,  unless  it  leads  to 
dishoarding  in  the  industry  so  benefited,  it  may  actually  decrease  the 
total  use  of  resources.  Where  there  is  extensive  underutilization  of 
capacity,  this  is  the  most  likely  result.  Thus,  price  reductions  in 
goods  for  which  demand  is  elastic  have  a  problematical  effect  on  full 
use. 

On  the  other  hand,  price  reductions  in  commodities  for  which 
demand  is  relatively  inelastic  free  purchasing  power  for  expenditures 
in  other  directions.  Unless  there  is  a  net  increase  in  hoarding,  there- 
fore, the  effect  on  the  economy  is  hkely  to  be  stimulative.  This  is  the 
paradox  of  pricing  policy  in  an  economy  characterized  by  less  than 
full  use  of  "resources.  In  those  industries  in  which  demand  is  elastic, 
private  interest  may  dictate  lower  prices  of  problematical  social  value 
while  in  those  industries  in  which  demand  is  relatively  inelastic,  private 
interests  may  dictate  high  prices  which  bring  upon  industry  and  the 
economy  the  consequences  it  is  most  anxious  to  avoid — reduced 
demand,  unemployment,  lower  income. 

On  the  other  hand,  any  individual  firm  (no  matter  how  large)  which 
attempted  alone  to  implement  a  contrary  policy  would  probably  en- 
danger its  fmancial  solvency.  To  be  effective  in  stimulating  an 
increase  in  demand  (despite  existing  price  inelasticity  on  the  assump- 
tion that  other  things  are  equal),  price  changes  must  cut  across  indus- 
tries and  complementary  goods  and  must  be  integrated  with  invest- 
ment schedules  and  a  monetary  policy  conducive  to  such  investment. 
The  attainment  of  such  a  coordinated  program  is  beyond  the  scope 
of  any  given  firm  or  industry,  no  matter  how  well-disposed  it  may  be. 

Wherever  (for  any  reason)  the  size  of  the  individual  firm  is  so  large 
as  to  force  or  induce  price  leadership,  or  the  number  of  sellers  of  a 
relatively  homogeneous  commodity  in  a  given  market  is  so  small  that 
each  determines  his  pricing  policy  with  reference  to  the  price  elas- 
ticity of  the  market  demand  for  the  industry  product  rather  than  the 
cross-elasticity  of  the  demand  for  liis  own  output,  this  confhct  between 
private  and  social  interest  in  pricuig  policy  is  of  paramount  importance. 
To  break  up  existing  corporations  by  law  into  units  sufficiently  small 
to  resolve  this  confhct,  although  in  many  instances  the  obvious  pro- 
cedure, would  in  many  others  be  inconsistent  with  the  trend  of  legal 
and  judicial  opinion  over  the  past  half  century,  and,  in  some,  would 
be  inconsistent  with  the  economics  of  production  and  distribution. 
To  subject  such  industries  to  direct  Government  control  would  project 
the  economy  into  a  maze  of  bureaucratic  regimentation  inconsistent 
with  democratic  institutions  and  processes  of  dubious  merit  unless  a 
positive  and  integrated  program  of  desirable  behavior  had  been  de- 
vised, and  of  doubtful  necessity  if  such  criteria  of  desirable  price 
behavior  had  been  defined  and  Government  was  ready  to  implement 
them  with  a  consistent  monetary  and  investment  policy. 

I  urge  upon  this  committee  the  necessity  for  a  permanent  Federal 
agency  empowered  to  coUect  from  basic  industries  necessary  informa- 

'  Dr.  Currie's  testimony  appears  in  Hearings,  Part  9. 


13642        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

tion  with  regard  to  price,  sales,  costs,  and  investment  which  would 
permit  it  to  devise  criteria  of  desirable  and  possible  price  changes  and, 
through  other  Government  agencies,  to  coordinate  such  a  program 
with  .public  and  public  utility  investment  schedules  and  with  central 
banking  policy. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  are  not  intimating  the  structure  of 
our  political  and  economic  system,  are  you? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  What  do  you  mean  by  the  structure  of  our  political 
and  economic  system? 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  think  your  observation  might  indicate 
that  if  the  Government  had  determined  to  take  over  the  control  of 
private  industry,  then  there  would  be  no  legal  obstacle  to  that  objec- 
tive.    You  didn't  mean  to  say  that? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  didn't  say  that. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  didn't  mean  to  convey  that  idea? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  didn't  mean  to  convey  that  idea.  I  am  not  a 
lawyer  and  therefore  I  am  not  qualified  to  make  any  statement  of 
that  sort.  What  I  did  intimate  is  that  the  pulverization  of  industry, 
the  breaking  up  of  large  corporations,  might  well  be  inconsistent  with 
the  legal  policy  which  has  been  followed  as  indicated  by  statutes  and 
as  indicated  also  by  interpretations  of  the  court. 

Dr.  Kreps.  In  other  words,  if  there  were  a  large  number  of  units 
in  an  industry,  cross-elasticity  of  demand  would  be  the  important 
consideration? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes;  that  is,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  the  only  reason 
why V  anyon  could  assume  that  private  business  interest,  which  is 
undoubtedly  to  maximize  profits  or,  as  is  often  unfortunately  the 
case,  to  minimize  losses,  is  consistent  with  social  interest  or  with  the 
interests  of  the  economy  as  a  whole.  It  is  the  impact  of  such  self- 
interest  which  alone  would  lead  to  a  maximization  of  output  governed 
only  by  the  producer's  own  cost  situation. 

This  means  that  in  fixing  price  or  production  policies,  one  thinks 
primarily  in  terms  of  what  I  have  called  the  cross-elasticity  of  demand, 
the  demand  for  the  product  of  the  individual  firm  on  the  assumption 
that  its  price  is  not  necessarily  met  at  the  moment  by  its  rivals.  So 
soon  as  the  number  of  sellers  becomes  suflSciently  small  that  it  is 
impossible  for  anyone  to  operate  on  that  basis,  but  each  must  consider 
the  impact  of  his  price  and  production  policies  on  his  rivals,  then  he 
tends  to  determine  his  pricing  policy  with  relation  to  a  measure  of 
the  elasticity  of  the  market  demand. 

Now,  in  a  competitive  industry,  I  have  no  doubt  that  you  would 
find  the  market  demand  had  much  the  same  inelasticity  that  Dr. 
Yntema  has  found  in  steel.  That  does  not  affect  pricing  poHcy  in 
such  competitive  industries  so  long  as  the  number  of  sellers  is  so  large 
that  each  one  governs  his  price  with  relation  to  his  cost. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Dr.  deChazeau,  do  you  mean  by  that  that  this  cross- 
elasticity  of  demand  is  simply  another  name  for  competition,  price 
competition? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  think  it  is  one  of  the  essential  conditions  of 
price  competition.  I  have  used  it  merely  as  a  shorthand  in  order  to 
preclude  using  a  long  phrase  each  time. 

Mr.  Wooden.  You  would  think  it  might  be  said  to  he  the  equivalent 
of  price  competition   cross-elasticity? 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECTONOMIC  POWER  13643 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  would  say  that  it  is  the  essential  condition  of  it, 
and  I  would  say  that  cross-elasticity  of  demand  ceases  to  be  important 
as  soon  as  the  number  of  sellers  is  sufficiently  small  that  each  one 
must  take  into  consideration  the  action  of  his  rivals. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Do  you  mean  by  that  that  price  competition  is 
something  that,  so  to  speak,  is  'impracticable  among  heavyweights 
but  it  is  all  right  among  hghtweights  and  middleweights,  or  what? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Let  me  correct  a  possible  misinterpretation. 
You  may  have  price  competition.  What  I  am  talking  about  is  th^ 
assumed  socially  desirable  effects  of  price  competition.  In  fact,  when 
you  get  price  competition  among  large  firms,  you  may  well  cut  far 
below  your  costs  with  unfortunate  effects  both  in  that  industry  and 
for  the  economy. 

I  wouldn't  want  to  discuss  that  at  any  great  length  at  this  time. 

Dr.  Keeps.  In  clearing  up  Mr.  Wooden's  question  concerning  full 
competition,  isn't  the  demand  for  the  product  of  the  individual  firm 
infinite? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  true  on  the  assumption  that  you  have 
complete  homogeneity  of  product. 

Dr.  Kreps.  In  other  words,  business  policy  where  the  number  of 
units  are  large  is  always  based  on  the  practical  experience  that,  by 
reducing  prices  they  can  get  any  amount  of  increased  demand? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  For  that  reason  it  isn't  necessary  to  reduce  price 
because  they  can  sell  their  entire  output  at  the  market  price. 

Dr.  Kreps.  That's  right.  Now,  business  policy,  and  meaning  by 
business  policy,  policy  which  individual  businessmen  must  follow  in 
an  industry  where  the  number  of  sellers  is  small,  has  to  assum'e  that 
demand  is  inelastic.     Is  that  correct? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Not  to  assume  it;  it  has  to  measure  market  de- 
mand rather  than  the  demand  for  the  product  of  the  individual  firm, 
and  it  finds,  as  Dr.  Yntema  indicates,  that  that  demand  tends  to  be 
relatively  inelastic.  I  have  no  reason  to  doubt  that  that  relative  in- 
elasticity (i.  e.,  the  price  elasticity  of  the  demand  on  the  assumption 
^that  other  things  are  equal)  is  probably  correct.  I  do  not  consider  it 
to  be  of  fundamental  significance. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Let  us  try  to  rise  by  gradual  stages  from  considera- 
tions of  business  policy  to  considerations  that  must  be  taken  account 
of  by  the  T.  N.  E.  C.  Is  it  true  that  there  are  a  number  of  practices 
which  are  on  the  whole  good  business  policy  'that  may  be  deleterious 
for  the  industry  as  a  whole? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  You  are  asking  a  very  broad  question.  I  have 
no  doubt  but  that  there  are,  but  I  am  not  willing  to  specify  ^t  this 
time.  What  I  was  indicating  at  this  time  was  that,  insofar  as  price 
policy  might  be  conditioned  on  this  short-run  price  elasticity  of  the 
demand  on  the  assumption  that  other  things  are  equal,  it  would  be 
deleterious  from  the  point  of  view  of  social  poUcy  and  that  it  roight 
well  be  deleterious  for  the  industry  as  a  whole,  even  though  no  single 
firm  in  the  industry  could  operate  on  any  other  assumption  withou  t 
endangering  its  solvency.  That  is,  a'5  I  see  it,  the  dilemma,  that  is 
the  paradox,  that  is  the  problem.  In  order  to  make  a  price  reduction 
effective  in  bringing  about  a  significant  shift  in  demand,  it  is  neces- 
sary that  it  must  cut  across  industry  and  probably  cut  across  com- 
plementary goods.    If  you  assume  that  the  prices  of  all  other  com- 

124191— 41— pt.  26 5 


13644       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

plementary  goods  remain  the  same,  then  a  price  reduction  in  the 
short-run  can  bring  very  httle  shift,  I  should  think.  I  should  agree 
with  Dr.  Yntema,  on  that  assumption. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Is  industrial  policy  always  consistent  with  economic 
pohcy?  That  is,  is  it  true  that  what  is  good  for  the  industry  as  op- 
posed to  what  is  good  for  the  individual  business,  is  always  good  for 
the  economy?  For  instance,  you  indicated  here  that  when  industry 
becomes  organized  into  few  units  it  has  almost  an  inherent  interest  in 
higher  prices. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  should  say  that  industrial  policy  may  be  op- 
posed to  the  general  economic  interest  insofar  as  each  member  of  the 
industry  is  interested  in  maintaining  his  position  and  precluding  or 
minimizing  losses.  From  the  point  of  view  of  the  economy  as  a  whole, 
the  bankruptcy  of  a  firm  is  a  matter  of  no  importance.  It  may  be  the 
step  by  which  one  gets  greater  efficiency  and  greater  progress. 

Dr.  Kreps.  In  an  economic  pohcy  which  endeavors  to  maintain 
competition,  we  have  a  profit  and  loss  economy.     Is  that  correct? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes;  at  all  times. 

Dr.  Kreps.  At  all  times.  Therefore  it  is  not  necessary  that  each 
firm  in  an  industry,  in  fact  it  is  almost  the  surest  sign  of  lack  of  health 
if  each  firm  in  an  industry  makes  a  profit.  The  normal  situation  is 
that  some  firms  make  extraordinary  profits,  a  large  run  of  firms  make 
ordinary  profits,  and  then  there  is  a  marginal  firm,  and  then  is  it  not 
true  (studies  of  the  Tariff  Commission  have  indicated  such)  there  is 
a  group  of  "lunatic  fringe"  firms  with  bad  luck  or  bad  management 
or  what  have  you  that  are  in  process  of  elimination. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  right,  and  that  is  likely  to  be  characteristic 
it  all  stages  of  the  cycle. 

Dr.  i^REPS.  So  that  the  problem  that  the  committee  has  to  consider 
and  has  to  decide  before  it  accepts  whatever  is  valid  for  the  business 
of  an  individual  firm  as  being  valid  for  the  economy  as  a  whole  is 
whether  or  not  this  particular  Corporation  is,  let  us  say,  a  marginal 
firm  or  one  even  less  efficient  than  the  marginal  firm?  That  is  one  of 
the  problems,  at  any  rate,  that  the  committee  would  have  to  consider. 
Is  that  correct? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  would  be  correct,  particularly  if  one  were 
talking  about  the  level  of  costs  rather  than  the'  behavior  of  costs.  I 
have  concerned  myself  with  the  behavior  of  costs  rather  than  the  level 
of  costs,  and  have  not  raised  the  problem  as  to  whether  the  level  of 
costs  as  indicated  in  the  Corporation's  study  is  in  any  sense  character- 
istic of  the  industry  and  therefore  whether  the  Steel  Corporation  may 
not  be  a  so-called  extra-marginal  firm  whose  efficiency  is  reduced  by 
reason  of  its  size. 

Dr.  Kreps.  One  further  question.  Economic  policy  in  turn  has  to 
be  integrated  with  what  we  may  call  public  policy.  Man  doesn't  live  by 
bread  alone;  economic  aspects  aren't  the  only  aspects  that  are  import- 
ant. Sometimes  public  policy  as  expressed,  for  example,  in  the  tariff, 
obviouslj  departs  from  sound  economic  policy  in  order  to  give  the 
favor  and  the  cloak  of  government  to  special  interests.  Sometimes 
we  disregard  economic  policy  in  order  to  effect  a  policy  of  national 
isolation,  self-sufficiency,  or  of  defense.     Is  that  true? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  should  agree  with  that. 

Dr.  Kreps.  And  would  you  agree  that  the  province  of  the  Tempo- 
rary National  Economic  Committee  is  the  province  of  economic  policy 
and  of  public  policy  as  well  as  industrial  policy  and  business  policy? 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13645 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  was  about  to  say  that  I  think  the  statute 
under  which  we  are  operating  determines  what  our  province  is. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  In  answering  the  question  directed  to  me,  my 
own  feeling  would  be  that  obviously  the  committee  is  concerned  with 
what  is  desirable  policy  from  the  point  of  view  of  society  as  a  whole, 
as  public  policy  and  good  economic  policy,  and  whether  the  particular 
industries  investigated,  in  determining  their  own  policies,  determine 
them  in  a  way  consistent  with  the  attainment  of  the  objectives  of 
social  policy. 

•  Acting  Chairman  King.  I  presume  we  may  proceed  upon  the  theory 
that  in  weighing  these  various  questions  that  are  brought  before  us  we 
weigh  them  in  the  light  of  the  fact  that  we  are  a  republic,  we  have  a 
constitutional  form  of  Government,  and  this  is  a  democracy  and  not  a 
Hitler  foriri  of  government,  or  one  approximating  the  totalitarian 
attitude  of  goverrmients  throughout  the  various  parts  of  the  world. 
Isn't  that  right? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes;  and  that  is  why.  Senator,  in  making  the  last 
point  I  want  to  emphasize  that  it  doesn't  seem  to  me  that  the  alterna- 
tive for  this  committee  is  to  accept  business  policy  as  it  has  historically 
developed  as  inevitable,  on  the  one  hand,  or,  on  the  other  hand,  to 
regulate  that  industry.  It  seems  to  me  that  what  is  necessary  is 
primarily  some  form  of  agency.  Federal  agency,  empowered  to  collect 
from  basic  industries  necessary  information  with  regard  to  actual 
prices,  sales,  costs  and  investment  which  might  permit  the  analysis 
of  what  is  desirable  price  policy  from  the  point  of  view  of  society,  and 
that  might  also  be  in  a  position  to  operate  through  other  Government 
agencies  to  coordinate  that  program  with  public  expenditures;  with 
public  utility  investment  schedules  primarily — I  am  merely  indicating 
places  where  this  is  possible  ttironorli  existing  controls — and  with  a 
central  banking  policy.  Frankly,  i  consider  it  rather  futile  to  criticise 
private  business  corporations  for  thfeir  pricing  policies  in  terms  of 
results  before  any  criterion  has  been  developed  as  to  what  is  desirable. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  Could  ,such  a  criterion  be  developed,  in  your 
opinion?  I  mean,  assuming  we  had  all  this  information,  could  you 
then  sit  down  and  teU  the  Government  what  would  be  a  fair  price  in 
steel? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  shouldn't  presume  to  answer  that  in  the  aflEirroa- 
tive.  I  would  say  this,  that  if  such  a  criterion  cannot  be  developed, 
then  we  are  at  a  most  unfortunate  impasse;  because  if  you  have 
Government  operation  of  industry,  you  must  have  such  criteria  of 
desirable  pricing  policy,  and  if  you  have  regulation  of  industry,  you 
must  have  such  criteria,  and,  therefore,  in  dealing  with  private 
industry,  -before  you  can  criticize  it  for  its  actual  pricing  policy,  you 
must  have  developed  some  criterion  which  is  known. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  Assuming  that  we  concede  your  point,  that  com- 
petition is  impossible  in  the  steel  industry,  that  is,  if  it  were  possible 

Dr.  deChazeau  (interposing).  I  didn't  make  that  point,  but,  if  you 
wish  to  assume  it,  you  may: 

Mr.  Ballinger.  Well,  for  the  sake  of  argument  they  have  reached 
a  point  where  they  couldn't  afford  to  compete.  Do  you  think  reduc- 
tion in  the  number  of  steel  concerns  in  the  United  States  has  been 
entirely  in  the  public  interest?  WiU  you  agree  with  me  that  these 
concerns  have  grown  largely  by  the  processes  of  merger  and  combina- 
tion  and   acquisition   of  competitors'   assets,   I    mean    by  artificial 


13646       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Dr.  deChazeau.  You  want  my  opinion  and  my  judgment,  I 
assume.  My  judgment  in  the  situation  is  that  thej  clearly  have  not 
been  in  the  public  interest. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  You  think  a  smaller  size  would  have  been  better? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Well,  if  you  pin  me  down  to  what  constitutes  a 
smaller  size,  I  cannot  answer  for  lack  of  knowledge  of  the  magnitude  of 
economies  of  integration  and  mass  production  within  the  industry. 
That  requires,  at  least  as  a  starting  point,  some  sort  of  cost  analysis 
of  the  industry. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  We  couldn't  say  definitely,  or  you  wouldn't  be 
willing  to  say  definitely  that  we  can  produce  steel  cheaper  under 
these  giant  concerns  which  have  been  created  by  artificial  processes 
than  might  have  been  produced  under  concerns  that  were  less  inte- 
grated and  perhaps  subjected  to  the  competitive  system.  We  don't 
know  about  that,  do  we? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  No. 

Mr.  Ballinger.  We  have  always  proceeded  on  the  assumption 
that  whatever  size  it  arrived  at,  by  whatever  method  it  got  there,  it  is 
good  and  in  accordance  have  so  protected  it,  without  analyzing  the 
question  of  whether  they  are  or  not  efficient,  whether  they  result 
in  lower  costs  or  not.  I  am  pointing  that  out  because  that  is  the 
trend  as  I  have  seen  it. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  right. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  don't  want  us  to  deduce  a  conclu- 
sion from  your  views  that  this  committee  is  to  consider  the  propriety 
of  destroying  any  branch  of  the  capitalistic  system  and  turning  it 
over  to  public  ownership  and  public  control? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Well,  if  I  may  repeat  my  statement.  Senator, 
since  it  seems  to  have  been  lost  somewhere,  I  emphasize  that  to  sub- 
ject such  industries,  industries  in  which  competition  does  not  work 
purely  and  perfectly 

Acting  Chairman  King  (interposing).  I  could  assume  that  there 
are  industries  in  which  competition  does  not  exist  or  in  which  com- 
petition in  a  reasonably  short  length  of  time  would  result  in  competi- 
tion, even  though  temporarily  there  might  be  an  arrested  process  of 
competition. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  There  are  ail  sorts  and  varieties  of  competition. 
What  I  am  assuming  is  that  there  are  industries  in  which  the  size 
of  the  individual  firms  with  relation  to  their  market  is  so  large  that  the 
policies  of  the  individu^il  units  within  that  industry  are  not  condi- 
tioned on  their  own  cost  situation  with  relation  to  the  market  price, 
but  are  conditioned  on  the  reaction  of  their  rivals  to  a  price  or  pro- 
duction policy  or  investment  policy  determined  by  them.  In  the 
determination  of  that  policy,  taking  into  consideration  this  impact 
of  rival  policies,-  you  do  not  attain  the  same  type  of  price  competition 
that  you  would  have  in  other  industries;  and  that  price  competition 
which  you  do  attain  in  such  industries  is  not  likely  to  give  you  prices 
which  are  related  to  or  determined  by  differential  costs. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Let  me  turn  back  to  the  analy^.s.  Under  a  situation 
in  which  there  were  a  large  number  of  firms,  would  any  analysis  of 
market  demand  be  legitimate  which  neglected  cross-elasticity? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Analysis  of  market  demand  in  such  a  situation 
would  have  no  significance  so  far  as  tho  individual  unit  was  concerned. 

Dr.  Kreps.  In  other  words,  if  there  were  competition,  full  compe- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13647 

tition,  the  individual  business  in  an  industry  could  proceed  on  the 
assumption  that  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  its  particular  product- 
was  infinite. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  would  be  the  assumption. 

Dr.  Keeps.  The  less  the  competition  the  more  the  elasticity  of 
demand  diminishes  from  infinity  down  to  10,  5,  and  0.3.     Correct? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  No;  wait  a  moment.  You  are  now  talking  about 
the  market  demand  elasticity. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Yes. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  It  seems  to  me  that  the  market  demand  price 
elasticity  might  be  quite  inelastic,  much  less  than  unity,  and  still 
the  individual  units  within  the  industry  might  operate,  would  operate, 
on  the  assumption  that  the  demand  for  their  product  was  of  infinite 
elasticity. 

Dr.  Keeps.  That  is  the  point  I  wanted  to  make.  In  other  words, 
it  would  be  unimportant  to  the  individual  enterprise  that  the  elas- 
ticity of  demand  was  for  the  product  as  a  whole. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  should  say  that  it  is  of  no  importance  to  the 
individual  farmer  what  the  price  elasticity  in  the  demand  for  wheat  is. 
It  becomes  important  only  when  you  set  up  a  triple  A  which  is  trying 
to  restrict  output  within  the  industry. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Precisely. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  It  is  beyond  the  power  of  any  individual  farmer 
to  affect  that  market  price  by  whatever  he  might  decide  to  do.  Hence 
he  can  operate  on  the  assumption  that  the  market  demand  for  his 
product  is  infinitely  elastic  even  though  the  market  demand  for  the 
product  may  be  very  inelastic  and  in  the  short  run  is  likely  to  be. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Generally  speaking,  prices  have  gone 
down  during  the  past  25,  30,  40,  or  50  years,  in  steel  and  automobiles, 
in  wagons? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes. 

Mr.  Ballingee.  Not  in  steel. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  In  automobiles  and  most  of  the  major 
portion  of  the  commodities  that  enter  into  our  personal,  family,  and 
economic  life.     There  has  been  a  gradual  reduction,  has  there  not? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  my  impression,  Senator. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Although  from  studies  of  Dr.  Frederick  C.  Mills  and 
others  who  have  analyzed  recent  price  history,  is  it  not  true  that  the 
price  of  steel  and  certain  other  durable  goods  in  the  United  States, 
and  by  exception  since  1929,  have  stayed  relatively  high?  As  Mills 
points  out,  that  is  an  experience  quite  unique  in  our  history.  It  is 
also  an  experience  which  is  not  known,  for  example,  in  Japan.  The 
relatively  high  price  for  building  materials,  for  steel  and  for  producers' 
goods  in  general  during  the  thirties  tended  to  restrict  the  amount  of 
such  products  that  can  be  bought  and  the  amount  of  investment  that 
is  made  by  the  economy  in  general,  did  they  not? 

You  are  famihar,  I  take  it,  with  Professor  Mills'  analysis  comprising 
three  volumes,  which  tended  to  demonstrate  that  point? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  In  a  general  way,  yes;  but  I  wonder  if  v/e  do  not 
get  beyond  the  discussion  of  price  elasticity  when  we  talk  about  price 
trends? 

Dr.  Keeps.  Quite.  It  is  only  apropos  of  the  problem  that  high  or 
low  prices  have  no  meaning  unless  set  in  terms  of  other  prices? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  right. 


13648  CONCENTRATION  OF  l^XJONOiMIC  POWIOR 

Dr.  Kreps.  And  relative  to  agricultural  prices  and  food  prices  and 
other  items,  the  prices  of  steel  and  of  steel  products  are  still  relatively- 
high,  even  though  there  has  been  an  absolute  decrease  since  1921? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes;  I  should  agree  that  a  downward  trend  in  a 
price  is  to  be  measured  with  relation  to  the  prices  of  other  products, 
and  I  should  agree  likewise  with  the  point  which  Dr.  Yntema  made 
this  morning,  that  price  flexibiUty  is  most  meaningful  with  relation 
to  cost  flexibility.  That  is  why  it  seems  to  me  that  the  cost  analysis 
is  so  crucial  to  this  entire  discussion. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Does  that  finish  your  statement? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes,  sir. 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  had  intended  to  call  Dr.  Yntema  back  to  the  stand, 
but  in  view  of  the  lateness  of  the  hour,  I  should  like  to  call  Dr.  Yntema 
and  the  assistants  who  helped  him,  tomorrow.  I  suggest  Dr.  de- 
Chazeau be  recalled  to  the  stand  tomorrow. 

IN  MEMORIAM  SENATOR  WILLIAM  E.  BORAH 

Acting  Chairman  King.  This  is  deserving  of  consideration.  When 
we  met  yesterday  we  were  advised  by  the  chairman  of  the  committee 
of  the  passing  of  one  of  the  members  of  this  committee,  and  a 
committee  was  named  by  the  chairman  to  prepare  appropriate 
resolutions  to  offer,  to  be  incorporated  in  our  record.  The  committee 
has  acted  and  I  am  authorized  as  chairman  of  the  committee  to  submit 
the  following  for  the  committee,  and  ask  that  it  be  inserted  in  the 
record: 

In  the  death  of  Senator  William  E.  Borah  the  Temporary  National  Economic 
Committee  has  lost  a  quality  of  service  of  the  highest  order.  His  judgment  on  the 
national  economic  problems  with  which  the  committee  had  to  deal  was  broadened 
by  a  lifetime  of  distinguished  public  service  from  which  he  had  emerged  as  one  of 
the  greatest  and  most  consistent  champions  of  free  and  independent  business 
enterprise. 

His  gift  of  public  advocacy  gave  him  great  power  in  advancing  the  cause  of 
economic  freedom.  Public  faith  in  his  courage  and  integrity  was  so  strong  that  his 
presence  on  this  committee  became  a  guaranty  of  the  honesty  of  its  proceedings 
and  the  good  faith  of  its  conclusions. 

Yet  in  our  sorrow  over  his  death  this  committee  consoles  itself  with  the  thought 
that  it  has  not  entirely  lost  his  judgment  or  his  power  of  advocacy,  or  the  influence 
of  his  great  prestige,  Isecause  during  the  year  and  a  half  that  he  served  with  us  he 
left  the  imprint  of  his  views  and  his  example  on  every  member  in  a  way  which  we 
cannot  forget:  Therefore  be  it 

Resolved  by  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  in  meeting  assem- 
bled, That  this  committee  spread  upon  its  records  the  acknowledgment  of  its 
indebtedness  to  Senator  Borah;  that  we  constantly  keep  in  mind  during  our  future 
deliberations  and  hearings  his  counsel  and  example,  and  that  in  that  way  we  guard 
and  preserve  the  great  contribution  which  he  has  already  made  to  our  work. 

We  will  adjourn  until  10 :30  tomorrow  morning. 
(Thereupon,  at  4 :50  p.  m.,  the  committee  recessed  until  Wednesday, 
January  24.  1930,  at  10:30  a.  m.) 


INVESTIGATION  OF  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


WEDNESDAY,  JANUARY  24,   1940 

United  States  Senate, 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee, 

Washington,  D.  C. 

The  committee  met  at  10:40  a.  m.,  pursuant  to  adjournment  on 
Tuesday,  January  23,  1940,  in  the  Caucus  Koom,  Senate  Office 
Building,  Joseph  J.  O'Connell,  Jr.,  special  assistant  to  the  General 
Counsel,  Treasury  Department,  presiding. 

Present:  Mr.  O'Connell  (acting  chairman),  Senator  King,  Repre- 
sentative Williams,  Messrs.  Lubin  and  Hinrichs. 

Present  also:  Hugh  White  and  Walter  B.  Wooden,  representing  the 
Federal  Trade  Commission ;  John  V.  W.  Reynders  and  Walter  White, 
representing  the  Department  of  Commerce;  William  W.  Werntz, 
representing  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission;  A.  H.  Feller 
representing  the  Department  of  Justice. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  The  committee  will  be  in  order. 

Dr.  Kreps. 

Dr.  Kreps.  In  each  case,  the  testimony  of  the  group  that  has  been 
incorporated  under  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee 
has  been  given  to  Dr.  Yntema  and  other  members  of  the  staff  of  the 
Steel  Corporation  so  that  they  might  make  their  comments. 

I  want  to  say  that  all  of  us  are  anxious  to  avoid  undue  and  sterile 
debate.  All  of  us  are  equally  anxious  that  the  points  of  diflference  in 
the  debatable  area  are  clearly  stated.  I  have  asked  Dr.  Yntema  to 
make  his  comments  upon  Dr.  deChazeau's  remarks.  I  believe  he 
would  like  to  have  two  of  his  assistants  sworn  in  by  the  committee. 
Is  that  correct,  Dr.  Yntema? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  I  should  appreciate  that  very  much,  Dr.  Kreps. 
Mr.  Appert  was  primarily  responsible  for  the  study  of  the  costs  and 
relation  of  cost  to  volume,  and  Mr.  Lewis  undertook  the  statistical 
analysis  of  the  demand  for  steel.  I  shall  appreciate  it  if  you  will  call 
them  at  this  tinie. 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  would  like  to  call  Mr.  Appert  and  Mr.  Lewis  to  the 
stand. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  Will  you  each  raise  your  right  hand, 
please?  Do  you  and  ea^h  of  you  solenmly  sHvear  that  the  testimony 
you  are  about  to  give  in  this  proceeding  will  be  the  truth,  the  whole 
truth  and  nothing  but  the  truth,  so  help  you  God? 

Mr.  Appert.  I  do. 

Mr.  Lewis.  I  do. 

13649 


13650       CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

TESTIMONY  OF  HAROLD  GREGG  LEWIS,  INSTRUCTOR  IN 
ECONOMICS,  UNIVERSITY  OF  CHICAGO,  AND  RICHARD  H. 
APPERT,  ATTORNEY  AT  LAW,  RUTHERFORD,  N.  J. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Mr.  Lewis,  for  the  purposes  of  the  record,  will  you 
state  your  full  name? 

Mr.  Lewis.  My  name  is  Harold  Gregg  Lewis. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Address? 

Mr.  Lewis.  1535  East  Sixtieth  Street,  Chicago. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  are  instructor  in  economics  at  the  University 
of  Chicago? 

Mr.  Lewis.  That  is  right. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  are  also  research  associate  of  the  Cowles  Com- 
mission for  Economic  Research  at  the  University  of  Chicago? 

Mr.  Lewis.  Yes. 

Dr.  Kreps.  And  you  are  the  author  of  two  of  the  exhibits  which 
have  been- submitted  here,  "Exhibit  No.  1411,"  '  entitled  "A  Statis- 
tical Analysis  of  the  Dfemand  for  Steel,  1919-38,"  and  "Exhibit  No 
1412,"  2  entitled  "An  Analysis  of  Changes  in  the  Demand  for  Steel 
and  in  Steel  Prices,  1936-39"?    Is  that  correct? 

Mr.  Lewis.  That  is  correct. 

Dr.  Kreps.  For  the  purposes  of  the  record,  Mr.  Appert,  will  you 
state  your  full  name,  please? 

Mr.  Appert.  My  name  is  Richard  H.  Appert. 

Dr.  Kreps.  And  your  address  at  present? 

Mr.  Appert.  My  address  is  62  'Ettrick  Terrace,  Rutherford,  N.  J. 

Dr.  Kreps.  What  position  do  you  hold? 

Mr.  Appert.  At  the  present  time  I  am  a  lawyer  with  Mr.  Olds' 
firm.3 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  understand  that  you  were  formerly  instructor  in 
accounting  at  Fordham  University. 

Mr.  Appert.  That  is  correct. 

Dr.  Kreps.  And  you  have  assisted  particularly  in  the  study  of  the 
relation  of  volume  to  cost? 

Mr.  Appert.  That  is  correct.  I  have  done  the  work  under  Dr. 
Yntema's  direction  and  with  the  assistance  of  other  members  of  our 
group. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Dr.  Yntema. 

TESTIMONY  OF  PROF.  THEODORE  OTTE  YNTEMA,  SCHOOL  OF 
BUSINESS,  UNIVERSITY  OF  CHICAGO,  CHICAGO,  ILL.— Resumed 

discussion  of  united  states  steel  corporation  studies 

Dr.  Yntema.  We  are  glad  to  have  the  criticisms  of  our  studies 
offered  by  Dr.  deChazeau  in  his  testimony  yesterday  afternoon,  and 
we  appreciate  particularly  the  courtesy  extended  to  us  by  Dr.  Kreps 
and  by  the  committee  in  affording  us  the  opportunity  to  comment  on 
the  issues  he  has  raised.  While  many  points  were  mentioned  in  the 
discussion  yesterday  afternoon,  it  is  not  possible  without  encroaching 
unreasonably  upon  the  time  of  the  committee  to  deal  with  all  of  them. 


Appendix,  p.  13913. 
Appendix,  p.  13942. 
Irving  S.  Olds,  partner.  White  &  Case;  also  a  director  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13651 

I  shall,  therefoi'e,  restrict  my  remarks  to  those  which  I  regard  as  most 
important. 

First  of  all,  I  should  like  to  clear  up  any  misunderstanding  which 
may  exist  as  to  the  purposes  for  which  these  studies  were  prepared. 
They  were  not  made  with  any  idea  of  providing  the  United  States 
Steel  Corporation  or  the  steel  industry  with  a  formula  which  could  be 
used  as  a  basis  for  price  policy.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  steel  men  were 
well  aware  of  the  characteristics  of  the  demand  for  steel  and  the 
behavior  of  costs  long  before  we  began  this  study.  We  have  merely 
applied  the  methods  of  statistical  and  economic  analysis  to  the  facts 
and  presented  our  findings  to  the  committee  in  the  simplest  way  we 
could. 

Our  objectives  in  the  analysis  of  demand  and  cost  were  these:  First, 
to  ascertain  approximately  how  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  by  the  in- 
dustry responded  to  changes  in  price,  and  second,  to  discover  how  costs 
varied  with  output  from  the  data  which  were  available  to  us. 

We  have  presented  these  findings  to  the  committee  in  the  hope  that 
they  may  throw  some  light  on  the  possibilities,  and  on  the  limitations, 
of  increasing  steel  consumption  by  reducing  price  and  on  the  extent 
to  which  such  price  reductions  could  be  borne  by  a  company  such  as 
the  United  States  Steel  Corporation. 

Near  the  conclusion  of  his  testimony,  Dr.  deChazeau  said  that  if  our 
"analysis  of  demand  reflects  faithfully  the  businessman's  criterion  of 
desirable  price,  he  has  dramatized  the  conflict  of  private  and  social 
interest  in  pricing  policy  which  is  the  fundamental  issue  before  the 
Temporary  Economic  Committee." 

In  the  first  place,  there  was  never  any  suggestion  on  our  part  that 
our  analysis  reflected  or  had  anything  to  do  with  the  businessman's 
criterion  of  desirable  price. 

In  the  second  place,  and  more  important,  the  phrase,  "conflict  of 
private  and  social  interest  in  pricing  poUcy"  requires  further  clarifica- 
tion. 

In  an  economic  system  of  private  enterprise,  each  business  seeks 
and  ought  to  seek  to  make  the  largest  possible  profit  in  the  long  run. 
I  suppose  that  most  businessmen  would  like  to  get  a  higher  price 
for  their  products  than  they  do,  and  I  think  it  is  correct  to  say  that 
it  [would  not  be  in  the  general  social  interest  for  them  to  obtain  as 
high  a  price  as  they  woiild  like  to  get. 

If  this  is  merely  what  is  meant  by  the  conflict  of  private  and  social 
interest  in  pricing  policy,  it  is  an  empty  phrase.  The  real  question  is 
whether  the  price  level  in  the  particular  industry  is  such  as  to  warrant 
concern  for  the  social  interest. 

There  seemed  to  be  some  question  yesterday  as  to  why  the  steel 
industry  did  not  charge  higher  prices  for  their  products  if  they  could, 
thereby,  so  obviously  reduce  their  losses  and  increase  their  profits. 
Certainly  it  is  not  because  the  steel  companies  do  not  want  to 
raise  their  profits  from  the  levels  which  have  prevailed  over  the  past 
10  years.  The  situation  can  only  be  explained  by  the  fact  that  the 
forces  of  competition  are  great  enough  to  keep  individual  companies 
from  raising  their  prices. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Would  you  care  to  elaborate  that  point  a  moment? 
Isn't  it  generally  true  that  monopoly  defeats  itself,  that  by  stimulating, 
as  Mr.  Chamberlin  has  pointed  out  in  his  well-known  treatise  on 


13652       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

monopolistic  competition,  by  stimulating  excessive  capacity,  by 
causing  other  costs,  particularly  selling  costs,  to  enter  into  the  picture 
the  net  results  for  the  industry  may  none  the  less  be  disappointing 
even  though  the  factor  of  monopolistic  competition  operates  virtually 
unimpeded? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  tliink  you  have  made  a  correct  statement  of  the 
theory  and  the  fact  with  respect  to  the  sort  of  situation  you  describe. 
Frankly,  I  don't  think  that  is  the  explanation  of  why  steel  prices  are 
no  higher  than  they  are. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Although  that  is  the  only  possible  assumption  which 
could  have  justified  you  in  your  analysis  to  neglect  the  cross-elasticity 
of  demand  because  otherwise  your  whole  analysis  of  demand  would 
have  no  meaning  for  the  Corporation.  In  a  purely  competitive  situa- 
tion the  individual  producer  knows  that  he  can  sell  his  whole  product 
at  the  market  price,  in  other  words  the  demand  for  his  individual 
product  in  a  purely  competitive  situation  is  infinite.  Thus  the  farmer 
sells  all  of  his  output  at  the  going  market  price. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Dr.  Kreps,  I  think  you  impute  to  us  objectives  which 
we  did  not  have. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Not  objectives;  I  am  asking  you  whether  that  is  not 
the  assumption  underlying  your  analysis.  I  must  admit,  in  fact  I 
must  pay  tribute  to  the  candor  with  which  you  have  made  that 
assumption.  It  is  one  of  the  many  things  I  admire  in  your  study, 
that  you  based  it  on  the  premises  of  monopoly  and  monopolistic  com- 
petition. 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  point  I  would  like  to  make  is  this,  that  we  were 
not  preparing  a  study  to  be  used  as  a  pricing  policy  by  the  steel 
corporation  or  by  the  steel  industry.  We  did,  however,  prepare  the 
study  in  the  hope  that  this  committee  might  be  able  to  use  this  material 
in  appraising  the  level  of  prices  in  the  industry  over  the  past  10 
years  and  to  date  with  respect  to  the  possibility  of  further  reductions 
and  the  results  of  such  reductions  in  prices  upon  the  industry. 

We  never  undertook  to  deal  with  the  problem  of  the  demand  for 
the  steel  sold  by  an  individual  concern.  If  I  may  go  on — I  expected 
to  comment  on  that  point. 

There  seemed  to  be  some  confusion  yesterday  between  the  elas- 
ticity of  demand  for  the  industry  and  the  elasticity  of  demand  for 
the  individual  concern.  I  should  like  to  make  it  entirely  clear  that 
our  estimates  referred  only  to  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  the  indus- 
try, that  is,  to  the  relation  between  the  total  quantity  sold  by  the 
industry  and  the  price  of  steel,  and  that  we  never  at  any  time  at- 
tempted to  estimate  the  so-called  cross-elasticity  of  demand,  that  is 
the  demand  for  the  steel  sold  by  the  individual  firm.  That  is  not 
relevant  to  the  purposes  which  we  had  in  mind. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Mr.  deChazeau,  would  you  like  to  comment  on  that? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Merely  at  this  time  to  make  the  point  clear  that 
I  indicated  in  my  discussion,  that  Dr.  Yntema  had  neglected  that  and 
that  in  my  judgment  he  had  rightfully  neglected  it  in  view  of  the 
pricing  situation  in  the  industry. 

Dr.  Yntema.  At  this  time  I  should  like  to  comment  on  a  few  of 
the  points  in  Dr.  deChazeau 's  ^''^  -.fn*''  '* 

of  the  demand  fo^*  stool 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13653 

Dr.  deChazeau  said: 

The  assumption  that  other  things  are  equal,  a  necessary  condition  for  the  der- 
ivation of  a  statistical  measure  of  price  elasticity  from  a  time  series  by  the 
correlation  technic,  is  false  and  vitiates  the  conclusions  as  a  measure  of  the  effect 
of  price  change  in  a  dynamic  situation. 

Frankly,  I  think  that  statement  could  only  have  been  made  on  the 
basis  of  a  misunderstanding  of  our  study.  We  did  not  assume  other 
things  were  equal.  Our  statistical  analysis  made  allowance  for  the 
effect  of  other  factors  and  yielded  an  estimate  of  elasticity  of  demand 
which  would  have  been  the  elasticity  upon  the  assumption  that  other 
factors  did  not  vary,  but  it  is  not  a  measure  derived  neglecting  the 
effect  of  other  factors.  We  took  specifically  into  account  the  effects 
of  these  other  factors  and  adjusted  for  them. 

(Senator  King  assumed  the  chair.) 

Dr.  Keeps.  Let  me  clarify  this  point.  Your  contention  is  not 
that  you  neglected  the  other  factors,  but  that  you  assumed  them  to 
be  constant? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  that  is  incorrect.  We  did  not  assume  them  to 
be  constant.  We  corrected  automatically  in  the  study,  by  the 
methods  we  used.  We  corrected  for  the  effects  of  the  other  causes 
and  the  result,  the  measure  of  responsiveness  of  quantity  of  steel 
sold  to  the  price,  represents  an  estimate  of  what  would  happen  if 
these  other  factors  should  stay  constant. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Yes;  if  they  should  stay  constant. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Which  is  exactly  what  we  had  in  mind.  '  I  was  going 
to  ask  you  otherwise  whether  you  had,  and  if  so,  whether  I  had  over- 
looked finding  the  correction  which  you  had  made  for  the  fact  that 
depression  is  primarily  a  heavy  industry  phenomenon.  The  steel 
industry  is  the  major  industry.  Therefore,  the  impact  of  unemploy- 
ment or  of  restriction  of  production  or  of  prices  in  steel  upon  general 
business  activity  is  highly  substantial. 

I  was  going  to  ask  you  whether  or  not  you  had  made  any  correc- 
tion. The  answer  is,  I  take  it,  that  your  analysis  proceeds  on  the 
assumption  that  those  other  factors  were  constant.  As  you  just 
phrased  it  a  moment  ago,  you  proceeded  as  if  these  other  factors  were 
constant. 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  I  think  we  are  now  quibbling  about  language, 
and  I  think  we  understand  each  other.  I  should  not  state  our  find- 
ings in  the  words  which  you  used,  but  I  really  don't  think  that  we 
would  gain  anything  in  further  discussion  as  to  the  terms  which  we 
employ. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  May  I  make  a  statement? 

Acting  Chairman  King.  When  doctors  disagree,  the  patient  suffers. 
[Laughter.] 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  doubt  whether  there  is  a  real  disagreement,  and 
I  offer  this  merely  to  check  with  Dr.  Yntema.  As  I  understand  it, 
in  the  method  of  correlation  employed  or  appUed,  you  take  into  ac- 
count the  effect  through  the  concomitant  variation  process  of  factors 
including  price  and  including  business  profits  and  including  changes 
in  the  industrial  situation,  and  then  in  order  to^get  at  the  price 
elasticity  of  demand,  you  eliminate  those  changes  which  are  due  to 
those  other  factors. 


13654  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Isn't  that  correct? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  that  is  correct. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  what  I  mean  by  making  the  statement 
that  you  assume  other  things  are  equal  in  your  final  price  elasticity 
of  demand.  You  have  eliminated  the  other  factors  from  the  variation 
in  sales.  ^ 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Doctor,  are  you  a  sufficient  pragmatist 
and  realist  to  understand  that  at  the  end  of  the  month  or  the  end  of 
a  period,  a  business  organization,  whether  it  has  a  number  of  activities 
or  is  limited  to  one,  makes  its  findings  and  discovers  that  it  is  in  the 
red  or  it  made  a  profit.  You  admit  that  this  is  ordinarily  the  practical 
way  of  conducting  business? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is,  of  course,  the  fact. 

Dr.  Kreps.  We  all  know  that. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Do  these  technical  discussions  which  you 
and  Dr.  deChazeau  and  Dr.  Kreps  have  been  indulging  in  throw  any 
light  upon  whether  or  not  the  steel  industry  or  any  industry  for  that 
matter,  at  the  end  of  the  term,  had  a  deficit  or  had  a  profit? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  they  throw  a  great  deal  of  light  upon  what 
the  deficit  or  profit  would  have  been,  if  the  price  level  of  steel  had  been 
different. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Well,  then,  you  can  conceive  of  a  hundred 
different  reasons  which  would  have  added  to  the  profit  or  added  to 
the  deficit? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Such  as  the  level  of  wages,  the  prices  of 
raw  materials,  cost  of  transportation,  and  many,  many  other  factors 
that  enter  into  the  conduct  of  a  business? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  absolutely  correct.  We  assumed,  however, 
that  the  coihmittee  was  much  iaterested  in  the  relation  of  the  price 
of  steel  to  the  burden  which  reduction  of  price  would  have  upon  the 
indus,try,  and  some  of  our  remarks  were  addressed  to  thia,t  point. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Well,  the  proffessors  may  continue. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Dr.  deChazeau  said: 

As  a  criterion  of  pricing  policy  for  the  steel  industry  itself,  the  price  elasticity 
of  demand  measured  by  Dr.  Yntema  is  inadequate. 

I  should  merely  like  to  point  out  that  we  never  submitted  our  study 
as  a  criterion  of  policy  for  the  mdustry.  I  do  not  think  it  is  possible 
for  the  steel  industry  to  have  a  pricing  policy.  There  was  discussion 
with  reference  to  whether  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  was  the 
same  in  depression  periods  and  periods  of  prosperity.  We  simply 
do  not  know  from  the  examination  of  the  data  and  we  have  not  been 
able  to  find  out.  We  did  not  assume  that  it  was  necessarily  constant. 
Our  result  merely  gives  an  average  estimate  of  the  elasticity,  and  we 
should  welcome  any  further  light  which  can  be  thrown  upon  that. 
Again,  Dr.  deChazeau  said: 

If  other  things  cannot  be  assumed  equal,  Dr.  Yntema's  analysis  of  price  elasticity 
of  demand  cannot  be  considered  a  criterion  of  desirable  pricing  policy  even  for  the 
United  States  Steel  Corporation. 

With  that  I  should  agree,  but  I  should  point  out  that  we  never 
thought  that  it  should  be  regarded  a  criterion  of  desirable  pricing 
policy  by  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13655 

Again,  he  said: 

Irrespective  of  the  short-run  inelasticity  in  demand,  the  prices  of  steel  products 
must  be  adapted  to  the  long-run  development  of  volume  of  business  by  consum- 
ing industries. 

We  addressed  our  remarks  and  our  studies  primarily  to  the  possibility 
of  cyclical  fluctuations  in  steel  prices,  and  for  that  purpose,  the  study 
or  the  consideration  of  short-run  substitution  over  the  period  of  this 
cycle  was  relevant  to  our  analysis. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Shouldn't  you  rather  have  used  quarterly  or  monthly 
data  in  that  event? 

Dr.  Yntema.  There  was  a  good  reason  for  not  employing  quarterly 
or  monthly  data.  If  such  data  were  employed,  it  would  be  necessary 
to  bring  into  the  study  the  effect  not  only  of  the  level  of  steel  prices 
upon  the  consumption  of  steel,  but  also  the  effect  of  reductions.  We 
have  found  in  our  study  that  the  effect  of  a  reduction  in  steel  price  is 
to  scare  off  purchasers.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  if  the  price  is  reduced  the 
immediate  result  of  that  generally  is  to  reduce  and  not  to  increase  the 
purchase  of  steel. 

That  is  not  invariably  so,  but  generally  that  is  the  effect,  and  we 
wanted  to  abstract  that  and  leave  it  out  of  the  picture.  We  preferred 
to  take  not  a  month-to-month  effect,  but  to  take  the  effects  over  a 
year-to-year  period,  which  I  think  is  more  appropriate  for  this  par- 
ticular problem.  | 

Dr.  Kreps.  It  may  be  appropriate  for  a  trend  problem,  if  the  period 
is  sufficiently  long  but  practically  never  utilized,  is  it,  for  measure- 
ments embracing  but  one  major  cycle? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  it  is  in  this  case  the  better  procedure  to  adopt, 
but  I  do  not  wish  to  argue  the  point  with  you. 

Dr.  Kreps.  At  any  rate  it  is  contrary  to  accepted  statistical  pro- 
cedure, isn't  it? 

RELATIONSHIP    BETWEEN    PRICES,    DEMAND,    AND    COSTS 

Mr.  Woode;?;.  Dr.  Yntema,  I  understand  you  to  take  the  view  that 
the  demand  for  steel  has  only  a  minor  effect  upon  the  price,  or  rather, 
the  price  has  only  a  minor  effect  upon  the  demand? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  we  ought  to  clarify  that  statement.  Let 
me  put  it  this  way:  I  should  say  that  changes  in  the  price  level  have 
been  less  important,  and,  within  any  conceivable  range,  will  be  less 
important  in  determining  the  quantity  of  steel  that  is  sold^  than  other 
influences,  such  as  profits,  and  the  degree  of  activity  in  other  parts  of 
our  economic  system. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Well,  do  you  think  that  the  demand  for  steel  would 
be  affected  in  any  substantial  degree  by  an  increase  in  price? 

Dr.  Yntema.  You  mean  the  quantity  of  steel  bought? 

Mr.  Wooden.  Yes. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  it  would  be  affected  to  some  extent. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Only  to  a  minor  extent? 

Dr. , Yntema.  It  depends  upon  what  you  mean  by  those  terms. 
Let's  put  it  this  way,  that  it  would  be  affected  less  proportionately 
than  the  increase  in  price,  and  the  effect  upon  the  consumption  would 
probably  be  less  over  a  period  of  years  than  the  effects  of  many  other 
factors  associated  with  the  cyclical  ups  and  downs  in  general  busines^. 


13656       CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  TOWER 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  must  confess  that  I  am  not  clear  on  that  point. 
Suppose  the  price  of  steel  were  raised  10  percent.  Is  it  your  assump- 
tion that  the  amount  of  steel  sold  .would  not  diminish  by  any  more 
than  3  or  4  percent?     Is  that  correct? 

Dr.  Yntema.  But  that  is  a  rough  estimate.     We  pointed  out 

Dr.  Kreps  (interposing).  That  is  your  estimate  of  the  elasticity  of 
your  demand  curve? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Let  me  say  that  we  took  that  as  the  best  guess  we 
could  make.  It  may  be  lower  than  that.  Many  of  us  who  studied 
the  figures  think  that  the  elasticity  ts  less,  that  by  a  10  percent 
decrease  in  price  you  wouldn't  get  even  3  or  4  percent  increase  in 
volume.  Some  of  those  with  wHom  I  talked  think  you  wouldn't  get 
any  increase. 

Dr.  Kreps.  That  is  the  best  guess  you  could  make? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  the  best  guess,  with  the  evidence  we  have. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Quite.  Now,  let's  raise  the  price  20  percent.  Do  you 
mean  then  that  the  amount  of^teel  purchased  would  decrease  by  only 
6  or  8  percent?  "" 

Dr.  Yntema.  You  are  getting  near  the  limit  of  the  range  of  experi- 
ence now. 

Dr.  Kreps.  But  not  beyond  the  limit  of  the  charts  which  you 
submitted  yesterday  for  the  record. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  that  our  discussion^esterday  had  to  do  with 
price  changes  of  10  percen  generally.  There  was  one  case,  however, 
in  the  discussion  of  the  j  ice  decrease  which  would  be  necessary  to 
bring  the  1938  production  up  to  the  1937  level  where  we  talked  about 
a  larger  change  than  that.  Frankly,  the  particular  results  there,  the 
particular  quantities,  are  not  very  significant. 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  am  referring  to  Chart  B-5  of  "Exhibit  No.  1409,"  ^ 
in  which  you  give  in  rather  precise  terms  the  total  loss,  as  v^ell  as 
estimated  additions  to  deficit  if  prices  had  been  reduced  asindicated. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  that  ranges  up  to  18  percent,  which  is  within 
the  range  of  experience  on  which  our  studies  are  based. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Would  you  go  on  and  say  that  if  prices  were  increased 
30  percent  the  amount  of  decrease  in  steel  demand  would  be  only  9  or 
12  percent? 

Dr.  Yntema.  If  I  may,  I  should  like  to  be  excused  from  answering 
that  question.  I  think  it  is  in  a  realm  not  important  for  business 
poHcy.     I  don't  know  and  I  don't  think  anyone  knows. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Isn't  that  the  kind  of  price  change  that  has  occurred  in 
the  industry  according  to  your  own  figures,  and  therefore  the  kind 
which  may  be  vital  for  the  purposes  of  the  committee? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  should  say  that  if  you  are  going  to  effect  any  great 
increase  in  quantity  of  steel  sold  you  would  have  to  talk  about  changes 
of  that  order  of  magnitude,  and  I  think  that  if  you  are  going  to  con- 
sider those  you  must  immediately  consider  the  impact  upon  the 
losses  in  the  industry.  And  those  losses  would  be  so  great  that  the 
steel  companies  in  the  industry  would  almost  immediately  go  into 
bankruptcy  unless  they  could  pass  on  the  reduction  in  prices  to  the 
wage  earners  and  to  the  others irom  whom  they  buy  materials. 

Dr.  Kreps.  In  other  words,  steel  prices  you  feel  are  based  on  costs. 
Is  that  correct? 


Appendix,  p.  13781. 


CONCKNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13657 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  would  never  make  the  statement  in  quite  that 
form.  I  should  say  that  cost  is  one  factor  which  enters  into  price, 
and  it  is  a  very  important  factor,  and  the  relevance  of  cost  to  price 
depends  upon  how  long  a  period  you  have  in  mind.  Prices  might  be 
considerably  less  than  cost  in  the  short  run.  In  the  long  run  they  will 
tend  to  be  approximately  of  the  same  order  of  magnitude. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  will  remember  that  yesterday  you  submitted  a 
chart  of  indexes  of  costs,  actual  costs,  and  of  mill-net  realizations. 
As  I  understand  it,  mill-net  realization  reflects  pretty  well  what  the 
consumer  pays  to  the  industry.  At  least  that  is  in  substance  your 
contention.     Is  that  correct? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  that  is  a  fair  statement. 

Mr.  Reynders.  Isn't  it  corrpct  to  say  that  the  costs  are  a  deterrent 
against  going  indefinitely  below  in  the  price  range? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I'm  sorry;  I  didn't  heaTr  the  question. 

Mr.  Reynders.  Is  it  not  correct  to  say  that  the  costs  form  a  deter- 
rent against  undue  reduction  of  price;  that  is,  when  you  get  below  your 
cost  Ime  you  know  you  are  in  a  danger  zone  and  you  begin  to  hesitate? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct;  yes.  The  function  of  costs  in  the 
processes  which  establish  prices  is  to  set  a  downward  limit.  Or- 
dinarily a  businessman  will  not  undertake  a  venture  which  will  bring 
him  in  a  smaller  income  than  the  additional  costs  resulting  from  that 
venture.  That  is  simply  plain  common  sense  and  good  economic 
theory.     The  costs  set  a  downward  limit  with  respect  to  prices. 

Mr.  Reynders.  And  when  you  reach  that  cost  line  any  disposition 
to  take  business  below  that  cost  line  will  be  actuated  by  yo-ur  desire  to 
maintain  your  position  in  the  industry  or  to  meet  some  competition 
from  a  competitor,  which  may  be  wise  or  unwise? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes.  You  and  I  probably  would  use  slightly  different 
words  in  saying  the  same  thing,  but  I  should  accept  that. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Turning  now  to  chart  C-25  of  "Exhibit  No.  1409"  * 
which  is  on  the  easel,  the  lower  line  representing  prices  to  the  con- 
sumer substantially — — 

Dr.  Yntema  (interposing).  May  I  interrupt?  The  lower  line  repre- 
sents an  index  of  mill-net  yield.  That  does  not  represent  the  absolute 
amount  of  prices. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Yes;  but  it  does  mean  that  when  the  index  reaches  a 
low  of  somewhere  around  75  in  the  middle  of  1933,  the  actual" price 
to  the  consumer  was  probably  somewhere  in  the  vicinity  of  25  percent 
less  than  it  was  in  1926. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  that  is  correct. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Now  the  actual  costs,  on  the  ot^e'r  hand,  also  are 
indices,  are  they  not? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  the  top  is  an  index  of  the  average  cost  per 
weighted  ton  shipped. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Therefore,  irrespective  of  whether  these  are  absolute 
amounts  or  indexes,  the  relationship  shown  by  your  chart  is  the 
relationship  between  prices  to  the  consumer  and  costs  to  the  Steel 
Corporation. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Well,  if  I  were  to  say  that  I  would  qualify  those 
terms.     I  should  say  that  the  chart  shows  the  relative  movement  of 

'  Appendix,  p.  13835. 


13658       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

the  prices  to  the  consumers,  and  the  average  cost  to  the  Steel 
Corporation. 

Dr.  Kreps.  The  relationship,  if  you  will  observe,  between  costs 
and  prices,  therefore,  is,  if  anything,  inverse;  the  higher  the  actual 
costs  go,  the  less  theOopporation  tends,  historically  speaking,  to  receive 
from  the  consumer,  as  you  brought  out  yesterday. 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct  in  respect  to  these  particular  aver- 
age costs. 

Dr.  Keeps.  They  sell  a  smaller  volume  and  are  doubly  hurt  be- 
cause they  also  sell  it  at  a  lower  price  at  the  precise  time  when  their 
actual  cost  per  unit  is  higher  than  it  has  been  before. , 

Dr.  Yntema.  It  is  the  actual  average  cost.  If  you  look  at  the  other 
line  you  will  see  that  the  cost  prices  which  they  are  paying  for  goods 
and  services  do  tend  to  vary  in  the  same  direction. 

Dr.  Keeps.  But  these  deficits  that  you  have  estimated  are  on  the 
basis,  are  they  not,  of  total  costs  at  each  level  of  output?  If  you  take 
the  total  costs  and  divide  by  total  output,  you  get  average  cost,  which 
is  represented  by  the  upper  line  and  therefore  the  line  that  is  pertinent 
to  the  problem  of  whether  there  were  losses  and  pertinent  to  the  prob- 
lem of  whether  or  not  pricing  pohcy  was  actually  based  on  the  behavior 
of  costs. 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  I  don't  want  to  be  quoted'  as  saying  that  in  the 
short  run  over  the  cycle  that  average  costs  determine  what  the  price 
will  be.  That  we  all  know  is  not  correct,  and  this  chart  demonstrates 
beyond  any  possible  doubt  that  that  is  not  what  did  happen. 

Dr.  Keeps.  I  want  to  make  clear  for  the  committee  one  other 
problem.  I  would  like  to  have  chart  B-1  of  "Exhibit  No.  1409"  ^ 
again  put  on  the  easel,  please.  When  you  speak  of  cost  of  steel  you 
don't  mean  steel,  do  you? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  depends  upon  which  particular  statement  of 
mine  you  are  referring  to. 

Dr.  Keeps.  This  cost  that  you  have  here  measured,  "Relationship 
between  total  costs  of  operations  and  volume  of  business,"  does  not 
represent  a  particular  steel  product? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  does  not  represent  a  particular  steel  product. 
We  took  some  pains  to  point  out  that  those  costs  are  the  total  costs 
of  the  Steel  Corporation  excluding  certain  miscellaneous,  extraneous 
operations.  Those  costs  therefore  extend  beyond  the  production  of 
steel.  Just  very  roughly,  I  should  say  that  90  percent  of  those 
costs  represent  the  costs  of  steel  operations. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Your  figure  was  89  percent. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  say  roughly  90  percent. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Wliat  is  the  rest  of  it? 

Dr.  Yntema*.  The  rest  of  it  represents  the  cost  of  producing  other 
byproducts  of  the  steel  industry,  the  cost  of  producing  cement,  the 
cost  of  furnishing  various  transportation  services  to  outside 

Dr.  Keeps  (interposing).  Of  the  steel  products  that  you  have, 
how  many  would  you  estimate'are  roughly  included? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Well,  I  never  undertook  to  count  the  number  of 
steel  products. 

Dr.  Keeps.  But  it  is  many  thousand? 

Dr,  Yntema.  It  is  undoubtedly  many  thousand;  it  depends,  on 
how  you  define  a  product,  however. 

'  Appendix,  p.  13773. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13659 

Dr.  Keeps.  With  the  widest  difference  of  quality  and  the  widest 
difference  ia  price  per  pound  and  price  per  ton? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No,  not  of  the  widest  difference  in  quality. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Do  you  have  the  range  with  you? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No.  Let  me  point  out  now,  if  you  are  leading  up  to 
the  question  of  the  aggregation  of  different  items,  that  the  relative 
differences  in  quality  and  characteristics  of  these  different  products 
are  very  much  less  than  the  differences  and  characteristics  of  the 
products  which  statisticians  and  economists  commonly  combine  in 
.  an  index  of  physical  volume. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  mean  to  imply  that  such  large  differences  exist 
in,  say,  the  quantity  and  quality  of  bushels  of  a  standard  grade  of 
wheat  or  a  standard  pound  of  sugar,  with  which,  ordinary  demand 
and  cost  studies  are  concerned? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  that  is  not  the  point  I  was  trying  to  make.  I 
was  merely  sayiug  that  many  of  the  ind'^^'^s  which  are  used,  issued 
by  the  Federal  Reserve  Board  and  by  ot^or  agencies  of  the  Govern- 
ment, are  indexes  of  volume  of  production  composed  of  such  different 
commodities  as  iron  and  steel,  chemicals,  textiles,  and  so  on.  What 
I  am  saying  is  that  the  various  steel  products  are  more  like  each 
other  than  the  different  components  included  in  those  indexes  of 
volume  of  production  which  have  good  standiag  among  economists 
and  statisticians. 

Dr.  Kreps.  But  you  are  measuring  here  the  cost  per  ton  of  a 
theoretical  unit  called  steel  in  which  the  composition  of  steel  varied, 
did  it  not?  For  example,  in  1932,  did  the  figure  of  11  percent  for 
items  other  than  steel  hold  true,  or  was  it  considerably  higher? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  can't  tell  you,  offhand,  what  the  situation  was. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  did  not  stop  to  see  i  whether  the  composition  of 
the  unit  which  you  have  asked  us  to  accept  as  homogeneous  was 
actually  homogeneous  throughout  the  period? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  we  never  asked  you  to  accept  the  composition 
of  the  unit  as  homogeneous.  That  is  not  a  correct  description  of 
any  index  number  of  this  type  or  any  other  sort.  What  we  did  do 
was  this.  Instead  of  just  adding  tons  of  different  products,  we 
assigned  higher  weights  to  the  higher-cost  products,  lower  weights 
to  the  lower-cost  products. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Based  on  Values  in  some  ye^r? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Based  on  mill  costs. 

>Dr.  Kreps.  On  the  average  for  the  period? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Over  a  period  of  5  years,  from  1933  to  1937,  inclusive, 
I  should  say  this — speaking  strictly  as  a.  professional  statistician — 
that  I  would  stack  this  index  up  with  any  index  of  production  that 
you  would  care  to  name,  and  I  should  say  that  this  would  represent 
the  variations  in  volume  for  the  products  covered  by  the  index  with 
at  least  as  high  a  degree  of  accuracy  as  any  index  you  can  name. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  would  just  like  to  raise  the  point  that  the 
validity  of  an  index  depends  entirely  upon  the  use  to  which  it  is  put. 
You  may  have  production  indexes  which  cover  a  much  wider  variety 
of  products  than  the . production  index  used  here,  but  if  it  's  used 
merely  to  indicate  a  trend  in  production  and  not  used  to  determine 
a  cost,  it  seems  to  me  that  it  would  have  inherently  a  greater  validity. 
I  wonder  whether  Dr.  Yntema  would -comment  on  that. 

124491— 41— pt.  26 6 


13660       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  would  say  this,  that  I  regard  this  index  as  being 
more  than  reasonably  acceptable  for  the  purposes  to  which  we  have 
put  it. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  would  regard  this  cost  curve  as  being  as  acceptable 
as  the  cost  curves  of  special  products  which  the  United  States  Tariff 
Commission  publishes  in  its  cost  studies? 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  curves  used  by  the  United  States  Tariff  Com- 
mission, if  I  remember  correctly,  are  of  a  very  different  type. 

Dr.  Kreps.  They  are  also  accounting  costs,  are  they  not? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  but  if  I  remember,  they  represent  a  frequency 
distribution  of  such  costs.  I  don't  like  to  get  into  such  technicalities, 
but  I  must  point  out  that  those  so-called  cost  curves  of  average  cost 
of  individual  concerns,  are  entirely  different  from  this  type  of  study 
we  have  presented. 

Dr.  Kreps.  They  are  likewise  cost  curves  for  the  industry,  the 
only  difference  being  one  of  arrangement  of  the  units.  But  let  us 
restrict  the  question  to  the  nature  of  the  unit.  If  I  may  be  permitted 
an  analogy,  what  you  have  done  is  tantamount  to  taking  a  population 
of  50,000  individuals  of  variegated  races  and  tongues  and  nationalities 
and  asking  us  to  accept  a  figure  for  average  height  and  weight  as 
meaningful  when  the  number  of  children  or  of  Chinese  varies  from 
1  percent  in  1  year  to  20  percent  or  more  in  another  year. 

Dr.  Yntema.  May  I  put  the  question 

Dr.  Kreps  (interposing).  The  unit  itself  is  what  I  am  talking 
about,  not  the  arrangement. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Would  you  say  that  an  index  of  physical  volume  such 
as  prepared  by  the  Federal  Reserve  Board  is  useful  to  show  the 
approximate  fluctuations  in  the  volume  of  business  for  the  industries 
included  in  that  index? 

Dr.  Kreps.  What  you  say  you  have  given  us  is  an  actual  cost 
curve,  not  an  index  of  production.  They  are  not  the  same  nor  even 
similar. 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  but  the  question  is  fundamentally  the  same. 
'The  question  is  whether  the  index  represents  with  reasonable  satis- 
faction the  fluctuations  "in  the  quantity  of  these  products  produced. 
The  question  which  I  asked  you  I  think  is  equivalent  to  the  question 
which  you  asked  me. 

Dr.  Kreps.  The  two  positions,  I  submit,  are  clearly  stated,  which 
is  all  that  is  required. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  wondered  whether  Dr.  Kreps  in  his 
analogy  of  50,000  population  with  only  1  percent  Chinese  was  meas- 
uring their  physical  or  their  mental  or  their  other  qualities,  their 
capacity  for  work,  or  their  capacity  for  idleness. 

Dr.  Kreps.  It  would  make  no  difference  what  quality  you  selected, 
when  you  have  a  unit  which  is  as  heterogeneous,  which,  if  I  may  say 
so,  sir,  is  as  nondescript  a  theoretical  hash  of  varying  composition  as 
is  the  unit  called  "ton  of  steel"  in  this  analysis,  the  result  obtained 
is  subject  to  a  considerable  amount  of  debatable  evaluation.  Now  I 
want  to  say  immediately  that  if  I  had  been  in  Dr.  Yntema's  shoes  I 
might  have  tried  to  do  exactly  what  he  did. 

I  also  want  to  point  out,  however,  that  for  purposes  of  evaluation 
the  point  which  I  raise  concerning  the  homogeneity  of  the  unit  will 
be  admitted  by  Dr.  Yntema  himself  as  being  something  which  gave 
him  a  great  deal  of  worry. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  EC?ONOMIC  POWER  13661 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  that  is  correct,  but  I  should  say  that  the  range 
of  error  due  to  the  point  that  you  make  is  not  substantial  for  the 
range  of  accuracy  with  which  we  are  concerned. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Trying  to  be  a  little  practical  and  having 
some  little  practical  experience,  having  worked  on  the  farm,  I  was 
wondering  when  the  farmer  raises  alfalfa  and  clover  and  wheat  and 
com  and  potatoes  and  sugar  beets  and  all  farm  products,  and  at  the 
end  of  the  year  he  balances  up  his  accounts  and  he  has  sold  so  many 
tons  of  potatoes,  so  many  tons  of  corn,  and  so  on,  and  he  finds  that 
.  he  has  in  the  bank  $50.  He  has  paid  all  his  bills,  all  the  cost,  trans- 
portation, sales  cost,  and  so  on,  and  he  has  only  $50  in  the  bank.  It 
seems  to  me  it  would  be  pretty  difficult  to  go  back  and  say  that  "My 
cost  of  lettuce  was  so  much,  my  cost  of  potatoes  was  so  much,  my  cost 
of  sugar-beets  was  so  much,"  because  the  whole  activity  has  been 
consolidated  and  worked  as  a  unit  in  every  branch  of  that  industry. 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  It  seems  to  me  that  is  the  important 
question,  what  is  the  final  result  of  his  labors  during  the  year  on  the 
farm.  In  nearly  every  industry  with  its  various  activities,  its  various 
chains  that  lead  out  from  perhaps  a  common  center,  you  are  going  to 
have  cost  problems,  of  course,  various  other  problems,  but  after  all 
the  question  is.  Did  you  make  any  money  or  did  you  lose? 

Dr.  Keeps.  Would  I  understand  you  to  say.  Dr.  Yntema,  that  the 
knowledge  of  cost  accounting  by  the  farmer  and  by  the  Steel  Cor- 
poration and  their  knowledge  of  the  costs  of  individual  products  was 
probably  not  essentially  different?  They  are  both  essentially  equally 
ignorant. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  am  in  no  position  to  answer  that  question.  I  donH 
know  what  the  farmers  know  about  their  costs,  and  I  am  not  qualified 
to  say  how  much  the'  Steel  Corporation  knows  about  the  costs,  I 
mean  the  costs  of  various  products.  I  would  say  this,  however. 
Any  allocation  of  overhead  costs  to  different  products  is  arbitrary; 
and  as  soon  as  you  start  breaking  up  your  costs,  allocating  overhead 
to  different  products,  you  obtain  a  result  which  is  not  useful  and 
which  is  suspect  for  the  kind  of  purposes  with  which  we  are  here 
concerned. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Proceed. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  If  what  you  were  really  interested  in  was  whether 
the  Corporation  did  make  a  profit  or  did  not  make  a  profit,  would 
you  have  gone  to  all  this  trouble 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  that  is  not  the  reason  for,  nor  the  objective  of, 
the  analysis.  I  have  stated  our  objective  several  times  and  I. don't 
think  a  restatement  would  clarify  it,  so  I  should  like  to  proceed  with 
the  discussion.  , 

In  dealing  with  our  analysis  of  steel  prices,  volume  and  costs,  Dr. 
deChazeau  raised  a  large  number  of  detailed  questions.  We  appre- 
ciate these  criticisms  and  the  careful  scrutiny  which  this  document 
received.  Both  Dr.  deChazeau  and  some  committee  members 
attached  great  significance  to  the  extrapolation  of  the  straight  line . 
representing  the  relation  of  costs  to  volume,  to  the  zero  point  of 
production,  and  to  this  $182,100,000  of  fixed  costs  determined  thereby. 
Th^  point  was  made  that  this  extension  beyond  the  range  of  data 
might  be  subject  to  considerable  error  and  that,  if  in  error,  it  would 


13662       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

seriously  affect  the  validity  of  the  results  shown  by  the  study.  This 
is  not  the  case. 

Dr.  Kreps.  There  are  statistical  means  of  measuring  that  error, 
are  there  not? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Let  me  go  on  and  explain.  This  extension  merely 
gives  a  convenient  method  of  breaking  the  total  costs  into  two  groups: 
Fixed  costs  and  additional  costs  per  ton. 

Referring  to  chart  B-1  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409'V  entitled  "Relation- 
ship Between  Total  Costs  of  Operation  and  Volume  of  Business, 
1938  Conditions,"  instead  of  using  this  $182,100,000  w^e  could  just 
exactly  as  well  have  ^started  from  this  point  and  said  the  total  costs 
of  producing  4,000,000  weighted  tons  of  tonnage  products  shipped  was 
$405,000,000,  and  that  proceeding  b.eyond  that  poiut  but  staying 
within  the  range  of  the  data,  that  the  additional  cost  of  operations 
per  additional  ton  of  products  shipped  was  reflected  by  the  way  in 
which  tnis  line  rose,  the  slope  of  the  line,  namely,  $55.73  per  ton. 
The  question  of  the  extension  of  this  line  beyond  the  range  of  the 
data  is  entirely  unmaterial  to  the  point  we  are  trying  to  make.  It 
merely  gives  us  a  convenient  way  of  stating  our  results. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  would  like  to  point  out  that  that  point  was 
greatly  overemphasized  in  the  discussion  yesterday  merely  because 
the  question  was  raised.  I  indicated,  I  beheve,  that  the  extrapolation 
of  the  figure  of  $182,000,000  is  of  httle  importance  for  our  purpose. 
It  is  rather  the  character  of  the  regression  line  and  the  rate  at  which 
it  rises,  and  the  important  thing  in  my  mind  was  the  fewness  of  obser- 
vations and  the  possibihty  that  with  changes  in  the  allocation  of  costs 
you  might  get  a  different  type  of  distribution;  that  is  the  important 
thing,  not  the  extrapolation.     I  should  admit  what  Dr.  Yntema  says. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes,  Dr.  deChazeau  is  entirely  correct  in  this  latter 
statement.  I  should  be  in  complete  agreement  with  it.  The  import- 
ant question  with  reference  to  additional  cost  is  the  slope  of  this  Une. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Will  you  identify  it  so  persons  reading  the 
record  may  determine  the  points  to  which  you  are  directing  attention? 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  important  question  is  the  way  in  which  the 
dotted  Une  in  the  chart  rises  with  increases  in  volume. 

From  inspection  of  the  points,  I  submit  to  jou  that,  as  far  as  this 
particular  evidence  is  concerned,  a  straight  hrie  represents  as  satis- 
factory a  description  of  the  data  as  it  is  possible  to  obtain. 

Dr.  Kreps.  That  assumes,  first,  that  each  point  such  as  the  cost 
in  1929  is  accurately  estabUshed,  that  there  were  no  errors,  say,  in 
allowance  for  obsolescence  made  by  the  management  in  1929  which 
they  were  not  aware  of  until  1931  and  '32. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  shall  come  to  that  point  shortly.  I  should  not 
accept  your  statement  as  it  stands. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Second,  ^ou  have  absorbed  two  degrees  of  freedom, 
have  you  not,  in  producing  that  line? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Quite  so.  It  is  the  minimum  possible  number  of 
degrees  of  freedom  that  you  can  absorb.  I  don't  think  we  should 
brmg  this  in. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Wait  a  minute.  For  any  average  to  be  useful,  and  this 
is  a  form  of  average,  you  need  at  least  30  observations. 

Dr.  Yntema.  You  do  not. 


I  ApiMndix,  p.  13773. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       •  l^QQ^ 

Dr.  Kreps.  For  instance,  if  one  person  has  an  income  of  a  million 
dollars,  and  the  other  has  no  income,  the  two  will  have  an  average 
income  of  half  a  miUion  dollars  a  year,  will  they  not?  Such  an  average 
is  misleading,  is  it  not? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  that  is  not  correct.  You  do  not  need  30  obser- 
vations. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Then  you  need  to  correct  by  advanced  statistical 
methods  for  the  fewness  of  the  number  of  your  observations,  do  you 
not? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No.  Let  me  put  this  in  plain  English.  You  do  not 
need  30  observations  to  make  a  reasonable  case  with  reference  to  the 
relationship  between  two  variables  such  as  dollars  of  cost  and  tons  of 
production.  If  these  points  in  the  chart  B-1,  were  scattered  widely, 
I  should  say  that  any  line  drawn  through  them  would  have  relatively 
little  reliability.  If  these  points  were  scattered  in  such  a  way  that 
every  one  of  them  lay  precisely  upon  a  straight  line,  I  should  say  that 
there  was  almost  certainty  that  the  relation  in  question  was  a  straight 
line  relationship.  These  points  do  depart  slightly,  but  very  shghtly, 
from  such  a  straight  line  relationship,  and  I  submit  that  this  straight 
line  represents  if  not  a  relationship  of  absolutely  perfect  reliability, 
at  least  a  relationship  of  rather  high  rehability. 

Dr.  Kreps.  This,  of  course,  is  a  summary  chart.  The  imderlying 
data  do  show  much  of  the  wide  scatter  that  Dr.  Yntema  is  talking 
about.  This  may  be  an  instance  such  as  Dr.  Warren  Persons,  one 
of  the  initiators  of  this  technique,  frequently  warned  against,  in 
which  the  errors  or  residuals  due  to  errors  of  fit  are  perfectly  correlated. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  should  like  to  attempt  to  get  some  perspective  with 
reference  to  the  cricitism  of  the  cost  analyses  which  have  been  offered 
to  this  committee.  I  had  the  feeling  yesterday,  as  I  listened  to  the 
discussion,  that  the  points  suggested  were,  from  a  technical  point  of 
view,  most  interesting,  and  I  was  very  pleased  to  have  them  called  to 
our  attention. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  mean  the  testimony  of  Dr.  de  Chazeau. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes,  that  is  correct.  I  had  the  feeling,  however, 
that  perhaps  those  who  hstened  to  the  testimony  might  not  be  able 
to  see  the  woods  for  the  trees,  and  I  should  Uke,  if  I  can,  this  morning, 
to  put  these  things  in  their  proper  perspective. 

First  of  all,  I  should  like  to  call  attention  to  various  concepts  of 
cost.  In  the  long  run,  when  a  businessman  is  considering  whether 
or  not  he  shall  build  -a  plant  and  engage  in  a  business,  all  the  costs  are 
additional  costs,  there  is  no  overhead,  with  reference  to  a  problem  of 
that  type.  So  if  you  take  a  long-run  point  of  view,  all  costs  must  be 
regarded  as  additional. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Would  you  like  to  make  your  observations  on  costs 
after  our  witness  on  costs  has  presented  his  testimony? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  it  is  very  important  at  this  point  to  do  this. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Then  please  do  so. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Because  Dr.  deChazeau  has  raised  a  fundamental 
issue  with  respect  to  the  interpretation  of  costs. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Proceed. 

Dr.  Yntema.  There  is  no  possible  quarrel  among  us,  I  think,  with 
reference  to  the  additional  costs.  All  costs  are  additional  in  the  long 
run. 


13664       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

In  the  second  place,  if  I  interpreted  the  statements  yesterday  cor- 
rectly, we  were  criticized  because  our  costs  were  static,  not  dynamic, 
that  they  did  not  reflect  other  elements  which  changed  in  the  business 
situation  as  the  volume  of  production  by  the  steel  industry  changed. 

Then,  if  I  understood  the  criticism  correctly  and  some  of  the  sug- 
gestions which  have  been  made  this  morning,  we  were  criticized  because 
our  costs  were  not  static  enough.  Now,  I  submit  to  the  committee 
that  you  must  choose  which  concept  you  want  to  use  in  the  particular 
problem,  and  I  suggest,  therefore,  that  we  keep  clearly  in  mind  two 
ideas:  First,  what  you  might  call  dynamic  costs,  which  represent  the 
actual  history  of  costs,  that  is,  the  actual  costs  involved  at  these 
various  operating  rates,- without  attempting  to  eliminate  in  any  way 
whatsoever  the  effect  of  changes  in  efficiency  or  the  effect  of  changes  in 
wage  rates  and  other  factors. 

Now,  if  you  want  such  a  picture,  we  have  it  here 

Acting  Chairman  King  (interposing).  Identifv  it. 

Dr.  Yntema.  In  chart  1  of  "Exhibit  No.  1416",  entitled,  "Total 
Costs  (Unadjusted)  and  Volume  of  Business ;  United  States  Steel  Cor- 
poration and  Subsidiaries."  ^  On  the  vertical  scale  is  plotted  millions 
of  dollars  of  actual  costs  incurred  by  the  Corporation.  Along  the 
horizontal  scale  is  plotted  milhons  of  weighted  tons  of  all  tonnage 
products  shipped. 

The  fluctuations  in  total  cost  and  in  tons  of  products  shipped — 
actual  fluctuations  without  any  adjustment  whatsoever — are  reflected 
in  this  chart.  Now,  if  that  is  what  you  are  interested  in,  how  actual 
costs  did  fluctuate  with  volume  otoperations,  here  is  the  picture. 

I  am  not  advocating  this  as  an  entirely  satisfactory  picture  because 
the  other  dynamic  elements  in  the  situation  did  not  stay  the  same  in 
different  business  cycles;  I  am  not  advocating  this  as  a  statistically 
useful  concept,  but  only  as  a  representation  of  what  did  happen.  If 
you  extend  this  line,  you  will  find  that  the  fixed  costs  were  lower  than 
"those  represented  in  the  other  chart — B-2  of  "Exhibit  No.  1409"^ — 
that  they  amounted  to  some  120  millions  of  dollars. 

The  average  slope  of  this  line,  if  we  may  take  a  straight  line  to  repre- 
sent the  data — the  fit  is  not  so  good  in  this  case— the  slope  of  the  fine 
in  chart  1  in  "Exhibit  No.  1416"  ^  is  such  that  the  increase  in  cost  per 
additional  ton  of  product  shipped  is  approximatelv  $54.51 .  Now,  that 
is  something  of  a  coincidence,  that  the  additional  cost  in  this  case  of 
unadjusted  total  costs  turned  out  to  be  approximately  the  same  as  the 
additional  cost  in  the  case  of  the  adjusted  figures. 

Let  me  go  on  and  point  out  furthermore  that  this  average  line 
reflects  the  changes  in  cost  at  wage  levels  prevailing  when  the  wage 
rates  were  lower  than  -they  are  today,  except  for  the  last  few  years. 
It  is  however,  also  probably  true  that  the  wage  rates  today  are  more 
inflexible  than  they  were  throughout  this  period,  so  that  in  -the  future, 
if  you  made  up  a  chart  of  this  sort,  some  factors  would  tend  to  make 
the  additional  dynamic  costs  higher  and  some  of  them  lower  than  they 
are  shown  in  this  chart.  I  do  not  put  a  great  deal  of  reliance  m  it, 
but  if  you  want  a  concept  of  how  costs  do  change  in  the  business  cycle, 
without  attempting  to  adjust  for  other  factors,  I  submit  this  is  the 
best  evidence  which  we  have  available, 

'  Appendix,  p.  14030. 
>  Appendix,  p.  iSTTrj. 
» Appendix,  p.  U039. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13665 

Dr.  Kreps.  Wouldn't  you  rather  say,  how  the  allocation  of  cost 
changes? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  I  should  not. 
Dr.  Kreps.  Might  not  this— — 

Dr.  Yntema  (interposing).  This  shows  you  how  the  total  costs 
change.  There  is  no  question  of  allocation  here  except  insofar  as 
costs  may  not  have  been  charged  into  the  years  in  which  you  would 
like  to  see  them  charged.  There  is  some  variation  possible  in  some 
of  these  costs,  in  charging  them  to  one  year  or  another.  I  shall 
come  to  that  point  very  shortly  in  dealing  with  the  adjustments  we 
have  made. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Is  it  the  accounting  policy,  do  you  know,  to  charge 
costs  to  shipments  as  shipped?  Is  there  a  uniform  managerial  account- 
ing policy,  in  that  regard? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  a  big  (juestion.  What  do  you  mean  by 
uniform? 

Dr.   Kreps.  There  are  various  ways  of  allocating  depreciation, 
depletion,  and  all  the  other  items  that  are  subject  to  managerial 
discretion  ana  managerial  policy? 
Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Now,  you  can  allocate  those  in  various  ways? 
Dr.  Yntema.  Well,  within  some  range. 
Dr.  Kreps.  That  is  correct. 

Dr.  Yntema.  And  the  range  can  be  very  narrow  in  some  instances, 
and  in  others  relatively  large. 

Dr.  Kreps.  But  your  evidence  shows  here  that  the  allocation  of 
cost  as  historically  made  varies  uniformly  with  shipments,  does  it  not? 
Dr.  Yntema.  No;  I  did  not  say  that. 
Dr.  Kreps.  Is  it  not  rather  uniform? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  I  said  the  costs  vary 

Dr.  Kreps  (interposing).  Costs  as  determined  and  allocated  by 
managerial  decisions  determine  how  much  of  depreciation  and  deple- 
tion and  other  items  you 

Dr.  Yntema  (interposing).  I  should  like  to  get  the  subject  clearly 
in  mind  in  that  sentence.  It  isn't  the  allocation  necessarily  that 
varies;  that  is  something  to  be  investigated.  The  total  costs  do  vary 
with  the  shipments. 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  see;  that  is  what  I  wanted  to  get  straight. 
Dr.  Yntema.  The  second  question  is  a  reference  to  allocation  and 
I  propose  to  take  that  up  later. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHs.  When  you  say  that  these  are  actual  costs,  the  busi- 
nessman understands  immediately  what  you  mean.  From  the  lay- 
man's point  of  view,  these  things  that  you  refer  to  as  actual  costs 
represent,  in  the  first  instance  and  for  the  largest  part  of  the  total, 
out-of-pocket  expenses  with  reference  to  which  there  is  no  question, 
plus  an  accountant's  allocation  which  necessarily  involves  questions 
of  judgment,  and  there  is  in  that  fact  some  policy  question  in  terms 
of  how  high  those  costs  are? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  that  is  entirely  correct  and  I  am  glad  to  have 
the  question  because  it  is  one  of  the  points  to  which  I  wanted  to 
address  my  remarks  in  the  next  few  minutes. 

Mr.  Werntz.  May  I  ask  there,  wouldn't  it  be  possible  for  the 
management  to  allocate  cash  maintenance  costs  between  the  years? 


13666       CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Dr.  Yntema.  Would  you  let  me  come  to  that  in  just  a  moment? 
I  think  we  will  get  a  more  systematic  treatment  of  the  subject  if 
you  could  defer  the  question  for  the  time  being. 

ANALYSIS   OF   OPERATING    COSTS 

Dr.  Yntema.  As  I  said,  I  think  it  is  useful  to  get  some  perspective, 
and  I  suggest  that  as  a  means  of  procedure,  we  refer  to  Table  8  in 
"Exhibit  No.  1416'V  this  table  being  entitled,  "Analysis  of  Operating 
Costs  into  Components,  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Sub- 
sidiaries." 

Mr.  O'CoNNELL.  What  is  the  name  of  the  pamphlet? 

Dr.  Yntema.  It  is  "Exhibit  No.  1416." 

Mr.  O'CoNNELL.  Yes;  but  the  name? 

Dr.  Yntema.  It  is  entitled,  "An  Analysis  of  Steel  Prices,  Volume, 
and  Costs — Controlling  Limitations  on  Price  Reductions." 

For  the.period  1927  to  1938,  the  costs  in  the  various  classifications 
are  there  aggregated.  The  total  costs  for  that  period  excluding  certain 
miscellaneous  items  not  connected  with  operations,  amounted  to 
approximately  $7,900,000,000.  Of  that  total,  two  components  ac- 
counted for  a  very  large  proportion,  namely,  pay  roll,  $3,614,000,000, 
which  accounted  for  45.8  percent  of  the  total.  (Percentages  are  not 
in  the  table,  I  am  supplying  them  from  other  computations.) 

The  item  "Other  expenses"  on  the  extreme  right  of  the  table  ac- 
counted for  38.1  percent.  Those  two  expenses,  pay  roll  and  other 
expenses,  accounted  together  for  83.9  percent  of  the  total  expenses. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Could  you  give  us  some  illumination  upon  what  "Other 
expenses"  are?     It  is  such  a  large  item,  almost  as  large  as  pay  rolls. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes;  may  I  come  to  that  in  just  a  moment?  I  want 
to  take  up  in' detail  the  adjustment  of  these  items. 

Of  the  remainder,  depreciation,  and  depletion,  concerning  which 
you  may  hear  much  in  the  discussion,  accounted  for  only  8  percent 
of  the  total;  taxes,  other  than  Federal  income  and  profits  taxes  and 
social-security  taxes,  accounted  for  5.4  percent  of  the  total;  the  other 
items  are  minor:  interest,  1.5  percent;  pensions,  0.9  percent;  and 
social-security  taxes,  0.4  percent. 

I  suggest,  therefore,  that  we  focus  our  attention  primarily  on  those 
items  which  constitute  the  bulk  of  the  costs,  because  it  is  only  sub- 
stantial errors  in  those  items  which  could  seriously  affect  the  results 
obtained  in  our  adjusted  costs. 

From  chart  B-2  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409,"  also  appearing  in  "Exhibit 
No.  1416,"  entitled,  "An  Analysis  of  Steel  Prices,  Volume,  and  Costs," 
as  chart  13  ^  in  that  document,  the  chart  title  being  "Composition  of 
Total  Costs  of  Operation  in  Relation  to  Volume  of  Business,"  it  is 
possible  to  get  visually  some  impression  as  to  the  relative  importance 
of  these  components.  It  is  easy  to  see  that  the  pay  roll  is  the  biggest 
item  in  the  total;  that 'the  goods  and  services  purcliased  from  others 
constitute  the  next  biggest  item  in  the  total;  and  that  in  comparison 
•with  these  two,  the  other  items  are  of  relatively  minor  significance. 

Let  us  consider  the  pay  roU.  The  pay  roll  represents  the  out-of- 
pocket  expense  of  the  Corporation  for  salaries  and  wages.  Of  that 
total,  the  salaries  account  for  a  relatively  small  proportion.    That  is 

>  Appendix,  p.  14040. 
» Appendix,  p.  14067. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13667 

represented  in  one  of  the  charts  which  has  been  submitted  to  you, 
chart  E-4  of  "Exhibit  No.  1409,"  ^  and  if  you  care  to  have  it  shown, 
we  can  offer  it  on  the  easel. 

Mr.  HiNEiCHs.  Pardon  me,  but  are  bonuses  to  officers  included 
there?    I  don't  know  the  Corporation  poHcy. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes.  I  am  informed  that  there  have  been  no  bonuses 
in  the  Corporation  since  1930.  If  I  am  incorrect  in  that,  I  should  like 
to  have  some  official  of  the  Corporation  correct  me.  Before  that  time, 
bonuses  must  have  been  a  very  small  proportion  indeed  of  the  total 
pay  roll.    I  think  that  that  would  be  an  inconsequential  item. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Proceed. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  do  not  think  there  is  much  question,  therefore,  about 
the  allocation  of  the  pay  roll  as  among  the  various  years  with  reference 
to  whether  or  not  the  individuals  rendered  the  services  in  those  years. 
There  may  later  be  some  discussion  about  pay  roll  for  maintenance 
purposes  and  that  we  can  take  up  when  the  point  is  raised. 

Dr.  deChazeau  did  call  into  question  a  point  which  is  dealt  with  in 
this  next  chart.  It  is  E-17  in  "Exhibit  No.  1409,"  ^  entitled,  "Earn- 
ings Per  Hour  and  Production,  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and 
Subsidiaries,  April  1937,  to  November  1939."  On  the  vertical  scale  is 
plotted  the  earnings  in  cents  per  hour,  and  on  the  horizontal  scale, 
millions  of  tons. 

This  represents  the  relationship  between  average  hourly  earnings  of 
all  employees  and  production,  that  is,  the  monthly  production  of 
rolled  and  j&nished  steel  products. 

What  is  apparent  from  this  chart  is  that  the  average'  earnings  per 
hour  do  not  go  up  or  down  as  production  changes.  During  this 
period  the  wage  rate  level  did  not  change.  Therefore,  given  a  certain 
wage  rate  level,  the  average  earnings  per  hour  do  not  fluctuate  up  and 
down  with  the  rate  of  operations.  It  is,  therefore,  appropriate  in 
adjusting  the  pay  roll  factor  for  variations  in  the  wage  rate,  to  divide 
the  total  pay  roU  by  the  average  hourly  earnings  to  find  out  what  the 
pay  roU  would  have  been  if  the  wage  rate  did  not  change.  Perhaps 
I  should  repeat  that  again.  We  have  here  in  our  original  series  total 
pay  roll  per  year.  From  the  period  1927  to  1938,  there  were  variations 
in  wage  rates.  Our  adjustment  consists  in  dividing  the  total  pay  roll 
by  the  average  hourly  earnings,  and  as  the  chart  which  I  have  just 
shown  indicates,  that  does  not  involve  dividing  this  total  by  something 
which  is  related  to  volume  of  production.  That  gives  us  an  approxi- 
mately correct  adjustment  for  variations  in  wage  rates.  I  don't  claim 
it  to  be  perfect,  but  it  seems  to  me  on  the  basis  of  the  evidence  that  it 
is  a  reasonable  adjustment. 

Mr.  Appert.  Dividing  by  average  hourly  earnings  converts  the 
respective  pay  rolls  into  the  man-hours  for  that  year  and  then  multiply- 
ing by  the  average  earnings  for  1938  gives  us  the  estimate  of  the  pay 
roll  under  1938  wage  rates. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  What  you  are  saying  in  effect  is,  you  are  taking  a 
record  of  man-hours  worked  which  you  needed  in  order  to  arrive  at 
average  hourly  earnings  and  are  multiplying  by  the  prevailing  average 
hourly  earnings  in  1938. 

Mr,  Appert.  Because  the  evidence  indicates  the  average  hourly 
earnings  are  not  dependent  upon  the  rate  of  operation. 

1  Appendix,  p.  13871, 
» Appendix,  p.  c-sgg. 


13668  CONCENTRATION  OF  EtTONOMIC  POWER 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  All  you  needed  of  this  chart  was  to  demonstrate 
that  within  the  period  1937-39  average  hourly  earnings  had  not  been 
significantly  related  to  volume;  you  are  inferring  from  that  period  and 
the  behavior  during  that  period  that  that  same  thing  was  true  during 
the  earlier  periods  which  is  a  reasonable  inference  from  the  materials 
that  you  have,  but  might  be  itself  subjected  to  check. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes,  that  is  correct.  If  you  would  examine  the 
detailof  the  adjustment  which  appears  in  table  12,  "Exhibit  No.  1416," 
"An  Analysis  of  Steel  Prices,  Volume,  and  Costs,"  '  you  would  find 
some  further  light  on  your  question.  You  will  notice  that  for  the 
first  5  years,  1927  tlirough  1931,  the  average  earnings  stayed  almost 
constant,  although  there  were  fairly  considerable  changes  in  vol- 
ume over  that  period,  and  you  could  by  inspection  of  the  adjusted 
figures  find  out  whether  the  relation  of  those  observations  to  volume 
was  roughly  the  same  as  some  of  the  others.  That  is  merely  an  addi- 
tional check  upoT;  the  calculations. 

We  don't  claim  perfection  for  this.  If  wc  could  have  made  a  direct 
index  of  wage  rates  and  salary  rates,  we  would  have  preferred  to  do  it 
that  way.  We  have  used  the  best  teclmic  we  can,  and  we  leave  it  to 
your  judgment  as  to  how  satisfactory  you  think  it  is. 

The  second  point  to  which  I  should  like  to  call  your  attention  is 
the  component  of  goods  and  services  purchased  from  others.  (Refer- 
ring to  chart  B-2  of  "Exhibit  No.  1409,"  entitled  "Composition  of 
Total  Costs  of  Operation  in  Relation  to  Volume  of  Business.")  ^  The 
adjustment  of  that  item  is,  I  think,  the  crudest  part  of  our  statistical 
analysis.  Let  us  be  quite  frank  about  it.  I  should  have  been  much 
better  satisfied  myself  if  it  had  been  possible  to  take  the  goods  and 
services  purchased  from  others,  to  break  them  up  by  classes,  and  to 
make  an  index  number  of  the  prices  for  each  one  of  those  classes  and 
then  bring  the  aggregate  together  again  after  adjustment.  It  was 
not  possible  to  do  that. 

The  goods  and  service's  purchased  from  others  are  composed  of  such 
items  as  raw  materials,  supplies,  freight-in  on  materials  and  supplies, 
public  utility  services,  professional  services,  and  so  forth;  it  is  an 
extremely  hf^terogeneous  group. 

Some  of  those  items  fluctuate  in  price  rather  widely  in  the  business 
cycle.  Some  of  them  fluctuate  not  at  all.  Now,  this  is  what  we  have 
done:  We  simply  took  the  bull  by  the  horns  and  decided,  "We  will 
divide  this  item  into  two  parts,  half  and  half;  one-half  we  will  deflate 
by  dividing  it  by  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  Index  number  for  all 
commodities,  excluding  food  and  farm  products,  and  the  other  we  will 
leave  as  it  is,  and  then  wc  will  add  the  two  results  together." 

That  is  a  very  rough,  crude  statistical  procedure.  Let's  be  perfectly 
frank  about  it.  If  we  had  been  able  to  do  it  in  a  more  satisfactory 
way,  we  should  have  taken  that  procedure.  Let  me  point  out,  how- 
ever, that  even  though  you  had  deflated  the  total  of  that  item  by  an 
index  number,  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  index  number  of  whole- 
sale prices  for  all  commodities,  excluding  only  food  and  farm  products, 
the  resulting  difference  in  the  additional  cost  per  ton  would  only  have 
amounted  to  about  $3.  You  get  some  idea,  therefore,  of  the  possible 
error  wliich  might  be  induced  because  of  the  incorrectness  of  our 
adjustment.    It  is  not  serious. 

1  Appendix,  p.  14(V42. 
'Appendix,  p.  13775. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13669 

Mr.  Reynders.  $3  per  ton? 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  additional  cost  would  have  varied  if  we  had  over- 
corrected  by  $3  per  ton.  If  there  is  an  error  due  to  this,  my  estimate 
is  that  it  must  be  a  relatively  small  item,  even  at  that.  This,  I  should 
say,  is  one  of  the  crudest  parts  of  our  analysis.  If  I  were  to  criticize 
this  myself,  that  is  one  of  the  points  to  which  I  should  call  attention; 
even  at  that  I  don't  think  it  vitiates  the  general  results,  the  general 
order  of  magnitude  which  we  show  here  for  additional  or  variable  costs 
and  fixed  costs. 

Dr.  Kreps.  In  terms,  however,  of  your  average  output,  10,000,000 
tons,  $3  a  ton  is  $30,000,000  profit,  is  it  not? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  not  very  large  in  relat'on  to  the  total  cost. 

Dr.  Kreps.  And  also  not  very  large  in  relation  to  net  profit? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  not  a  correot  interpretation  because  if  the 
additional  costs  are  reduced,  the  fixed  costs  are  raised,  so  that  it  isn't 
$30,000,000  difference  in  profit.    That  is  not  a  correct  interpretation. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  There  is  a  question  still,  of  course,  to  be  discussed 
as  to  the  possible  allocation  of  goods  and  services  purchased  in  one  year 
with  relation  to  volume  which  would  tend  to  bias  your  curve  in  the 
direction  of  increasing  your  apparent  variable  cost. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Both  ways. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Possibly  both  ways. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes,  and  let  me  point  out  why.  What  is  the  effect 
of  inventory  adjustments  in  bad  years? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Are  you  asking  me  the  question? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  You  have  the  inventories  and  the  data;  I  suggest 
that  you  tell  us. 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  effect  cf  inventory  adjustments  in  bad  years  is 
to  increase  the  cost  in  the  years  of  low  operations. 

Dr.  Kreps.  And  decrease  the  cost  in  the  years  of  high  operation. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes,  and  that  makes  the  curve  too  flat  and,  therefore, 
makes  the  additional  cost  too  small.  I  mean  that  particular  item  gives 
rise,  you  see,  to  a  bias  of  exactly  the  opposite  sort  from  this  which 
you  have  been  discussing. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Have  you  taken  care  to  avoid  that  bias? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  we  have  not  adjusted  for  that.  We  recognize 
there  are  some  elements  of  bias  one  way  and  some  elements  of  bias 
the  other  way. 

Mr.  Hinrichs.  Where  are  inventory  adjustments  in  other  expenses? 

Dr.  Yntema.  They  would  be  included  in  all  other  expenses  of  ship- 
ment. What  we  had  to  do  was  this:  We  had  only  the  consolidated 
statement  available  since  we  had  separate  figures  on  pay  rolls,  and 
we  took  those  out.  There  are  some  slight  compensatory  errors  in  the 
distribution  of  these  expenses  between  pay  rolls  and  goods  and  services 
purchased  from  others.  One  may  be  a  little  too  large  in  some  years 
when  the  other  is  a  little  too  small,  but  the  effect  of  inventory  charges 
into  cost  of  goods  sold  would  appear  here  in  goods  'and  services  pur- 
chased from  others. 

Mr.  Hinrichs.  While  I  have  interrupted,  you  said  in  answer  to  a 
question  by  Mr.  Kreps  that  in  view  of  the  magnitudes  which  were  in- 
volved that  run  up  to  a  billion  dollars  a  year,  pretty  nearly,  at  times, 
that  $30,000,000  was  a  relatively  small  item. 

Dr.  Yntema.  In  relation  to  the  costs;  not  in  relation  to  profits. 


13670  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  No,  no;  that  a  question  of  estimating  the  location 
of  one  of  these  points,  $30,000,000  one  way  or  another,  was  relatively 
small  against  the  total  magnitudes  that  you  have  plotted  there. 
.  Dr.  Yntema.  I'm  sorry  that  I  made  that  statement.  I  was  in- 
correct in  so  doing.  That  is  not  true,  of  course.  The  30  million  item 
in  the  case  of  a  biUion-dollar  cost  would  be  3  percent  and  in  the  case 
of  $500,000,000  cost  would  be  6  percent,  and  that  is  a  substantial 
deviation. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHs.  You  are  too  good.  I  thought  I  was  going  to  have 
to  stop  you  from  letting  30  million  go  by  because  I  don't  want  that 
much. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  May  I  clear  up  one  thing?  In  connection  with 
the  inventory  adjustments,  you  are  dealing,  as  I  understand,  not  with 
costs  of  goods  manufactured  but  with  cost  of  goods  sold. 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  correct. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  When  would  the  cost  of  goods  taken  into  inven- 
tory be  charged,  then,  in  terms  of  your  total  expense? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Any  inventory  adjustments,  writing  down  of  inven- 
tories at  the  end  of  the  year,  would  increase  the  cost  of  goods  shipped, 
would  increase  the  total  cost  charged  into  operations  in  that  year. 

We  come  finally  to  this  index  of  shipments  which  has  been  the 
subject  of  considerable  discussion  this  morning  as  well  as  yesterday 
afternoon.  If  I  were  asking  questions  about  this  index,  I  would  ask 
this  question:  There  is  a  proportion  of  the  products  of  the  Corporation 
not  covered  by  this  index.  I  should  raise  the  question  whether  or  not 
the  production  of  those  products  varied  in  proportion  to  the  production 
of  the  products  we  have  included.  We  do  not  have  satisfactory 
measures  of  quantity  of  shipments  for  all  those  other  products.  We 
do,  however,  have  revenues,  and  this  I  will  say,  that  based  upon  a  study 
of  the  fluctuation  in  revenues  of  these  other  commodities  not  included, 
and  upon  a  study  of  the  revenues  of  those  commodities  which  are 
included,  the  inclusion 'of  those  additional  commodities  would  not 
make  any  substantial  difference  in  the  index  nuraber.  .  And  I  would 
say  this  further,  that  if  you  set  20  different  statisticians  or  economists 
to  work  on  the  construction  of  this  particular  index  number,  they  would 
come  out  with  nearly;  identical  answers.  If  there  is  a  possibility  of 
agreement  on  something,  I  should  say  it  is  here.  I  am  quite  willing 
to  defend  this  particular  index,  as  a  reasonably  satisfactory  measure  of 
production,  to  the  last  ditch. 

There  were  many  points  that  were  raised  which  I  have  not  discussed. 
I  don't  like  to  leave  those  points  without  answer  to  them.  On  the 
other  hand,  I  am  extremely  reluctant  to  take  the  time  of  the  committee 
to  discuss  details  which  in  my  opinion  are  relatively  insignificant.  I 
don't  think  they  are  really  important  in  the  total.  I  am  perfectly 
willing,  however,  to  answer  any  questions,  if  any  member  of  the 
committee  or  any  witness  for  the  Government  would  like  to  raise  such 
question  with  reference  to  the  significance  of  any  item  in  the  cost 
analysis. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Dr.  Kreps,  are  you  through  with  the 
witness? 

Dr.  Kreps.  Yes.  The  witness  has  made  advanced  comment 
upon  the  presentations  which  follow,  and  I  suggest,  therefore,  that  the 
presentations  which  follow  be  regarded  as  presentations  of  the  other 
side  of  the  case.  ' 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13671 

Dr.  Yntema.  May  I  say,  Dr.  Ejeps 

Dr.  Keeps  (interposing).  It  was  impossible  to  avoid  it. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Let  me  say  this.  Because  of  the  fact  that  I  had  jfive 
documents  prepared  by  Government  witnesses,  I  have  not,  as  a  matter 
of  fact,  had  an  opportunity  yet  to  read  Mr.  Taitel's  statement.  All  I 
have  learned  is  through  comments  from  Aljr.  Appert,  so  in  responding, 
I  could  not  have  directed  my  remarks  pointedly  to  the  argument  that 
Mr.  Taitel  is  about  to  make. 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  Will  Mr.  Yntema  be  available  again? 

Dr.  Keeps.  I  should  like  to  recall  him  after  Mr.  Ezekiel  and  Mr. 
Taitel  have  presented  their  case. 

Mr.  Reyndees.  Will  that  also  be  true  in  regard  to  Dr.  deChazeau? 

Dr.  Keeps.  No,  Dr.  deChazeau  has  an  original  presentation  of 
the  Department  of  Justice  which  does  not  strictly  belong  to  Dr. 
Yntema's  analysis.     Dr.  deChazeau  may  be  dismissed. 

Mr.  Reyndees.  I  won't  be  able  to  be  here  this  afternoon,  and  I 
just  wondered  whether  I  would  have  an  opportunity  to  clear  up 
some  points  in  Dr.  deChazeau's  testimony. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Proceed. 

Mr.  Reyndees.  One  statement  you  made  was  to  the  effect,  as  I 
understand  it,  that  while  a  10  percent  reduction  in  price  might  not  have 
a  substantial  effect  upon  demand,  that  a  20  percent  reduction  would 
have  that  effect. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes,  that  statement  was  made  not  with  relation 
to  any  analysis,  you  understand,  of  demand,  but  merely  derived  from 
the  point  that  in  the  short  run  the  substitutabihty  of  one  raw  material 
for  another,  steel  for  other  products,  would  be  likely  to  be  costly  and 
likely  to  be  very  small,  and  that  particularly  where  the  price  of  com- 
plementary goods  is  not  altered,  is  assumed  constant,  the  increased 
deniand  for  a  given  product  may  have  quite  an  elasticity.  The  point 
is  made  that  with  a  very  large  decrease  in  the  price  of  steel  the  demand 
might  have  a  different  elasticity  than  with  a  small  decrease  because 
of  those  obstacles  to  substitution  and  to  increased  demand  involved 
in  unchanging  costs  of  complementary  goods. 

Mr.  Reyndees.  On  the  other  hand,  your  argument  visualized  a 
reduction  of  20  percent  in  steel  prices.  Isn't  that  true?  I  mean 
leaving  it  to  the  discretion  of  the  committee  sitting  here,  it  would 
seem  that  a  20  percent  reduction  in  steel  prices  would  be  something 
that  was  reasonable  in  the  order  of  possibility. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  The  percentage  used  was  purely  as  a  matter  of 
illustration,  merely  to  draw  distmction  between  a  small  price  decline 
and  a  large,  price  decline.  There  was  no  measure  there  of  what  I 
should  consider  possible. 

Mr.  Reyndees.  Would  you  wish  to  withdraw  that  suggestion  of  a 
20  percent,  or  would  you  still  have  it  in  the  picture? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  think  I  have  withdrawn  it  as  a  statement  of 
what  I  consider  to  be  a  reasonable  reduction  in  steel.  My  point  was 
merely  that  a  large  price  reduction  may  have  quite  a  different  effect 
from  a  small  price  reduction.  -^ 

Dr.  Keeps.  I  was  going  to  ask  Dr.  deChazeau,  if  one  takes  a  par- 
ticular product,  such  as  automobile  sheet  steel,  hasn't  there  actuall.y 
occurred  more  than  the  20-percent  reduction  to  which  you  referred? 
Wasn't  that  the  example  which  you  had  in  mind,  or  one  of  the  ex- 
amples you  had  in  mind? 


13672  CONCENTRATION  OF  E(?ONOMIC  POWER 

Dr.  deChazeau.  There  are  examples  of  such  price  reductions,  but 
my  point  was  a  purely  theoretical  point,  as  to  the  significance  of  the 
price  elasticity  of  demand  in  the  short  run. 

Mr.  Reynders.  The  instance  that  Dr.  Kreps  suggested  was,  I 
think,  influenced  very  largely  by  improvement  in  the  means  of  pro- 
duction, and  that  gets  into  the  continuous  mill,  which  we  know  has  a 
very  big  reduction. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Which  is  one  of  the  benefits  of  low  costs,  particularly 
when  producers  are  forced  to  lower  costs. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Suppose  we  let  the  witness  proceed.  We 
will  not  interrupt  you  with  questions  until  we  get  through. 

Mr.  Reynders.  Well,  I  think  for  the  general  understanding,  it 
should  be  clearly  appreciated  that  the  distribution  of  the  sales  dollar 
of  steel,  taking  the  year  1938  ^  was  divided  45  cents  for  labor,  38.9 
for  goods  and  services  purchased,  as  shown  there,  and  8  percent  for 
taxes,  making  a  total  of  91.9  percent  going  out,  which  is  out-of-pocket 
expense  for  any  manufacturer  of  steel. 

Now,  the  committee  here  is  engaged  upon  an  investigation  which 
will  give  the  Congress  a  correct  picture  of  the  possibilities  of  this 
industry,  and,  for  that  reason,  I  am  very  anxious  that  no  impression 
should  go  forth  that  any  reduction  of  that  sort  is  in  the  range  of  possi- 
bilities, taking  it  through  the  whole  range  of  price. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  May  I  answer  that  briefly,  that  the  total  expendi- 
tures made  by  the  Corporation  for  these  various  items  do  not  represent 
what  are  the  additional  costs,  associated  with  a  given  product.  Marry 
of  those  costs  are  constant. 

If  your  statement  is  that  the  Steel  Corporation,  in  view  of  those 
expenditures,  could  not  take  a  20-percent  reduction  in  its  revenue 
without  loss,  I  should  admit  it,  but  I  should  say  that  this  would  have 
nothing  to  do  with  the  possibility  of  reducing  the  price  of  a  given  steel 
product  20  percent. 

Mr.  Reynders.  Well,  that  is  possible  along  the  line  indicated, 
where  the  means  of  production  might  have  undergone  a  very  definite 
change. 

There  is  another  point,  Mr.  deChazeau,  that  came  up  in  the  latter 
part  of  your  testimony,  that  had  to  do  with  your  suggestion,  or  at 
least  you  said  you  disapproved  of  the  size  of  the  units  which  had 
grown  up  in  the  steel  industry  and  regarded  that — I  am  not  in  con- 
troversy with  you  at  all,  but  it  is  from  your  practical  contact  with  the 
steel  industry — I  understand  you  have  visited  many  plants  and  you . 
know  the  general  situation,  you  are  familiar  with  the  location  of  raw 
materials  such  as  iron  mines,  coal,  and  so  forth — in  that  connection, 
what  thought,  may  I  ask,  have  you  given  to  what  is  a  suitable  unit 
of  a  steel  plant  of  a  steel  corporation? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  have  given  it  considerable  thought,  but  in  order 
to  give  any  statement  with  regard  to  it  woidd  involve  a  very  complex 
investigation  wliich  we  were  not  able  to  make. 

Mr.  Reynders.  It  is  really  a  very  simple  one.  You  can  do  it  in 
3  minutes. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  The  point-to  which  I  made  reference  was  merely 
this,  that  when  a  plant  expands  through  an  increase  in  its  production 
facilities,  then  there  is  a  self-corrective  applied  in  that  expansion 
through  increased  cost,  in  a  competitive  situation. 

>  Referring  to  chart  A-S  of  "ExliiMt  No.  1409,"  appendix,  p.  13757. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13673 

When  a  plant  expands  through  merger,  which  in  part  reduces  the 
competition,  the  same  corrective  does  not  apply.  Therefore,  I  think 
that  one  can  be  suspicious  of  expansions  by  merger.  Now,  when  one 
presents  evidence  that  the  total  costs  of  the  Steel  Corporation  are  so 
large  that  they  cannot  make  a  profit,  whereas  other  companies  less 
weU  integrated  or  less  thoroughly  integrated,  less  extended  in  other 
directions,  are  making  a  profit;  then  it  does  not  seem  to  me  that  the 
case  has  shown  conclusively  that  the  price  of  steel  is  too  low.  It 
may  be  that  the  Corporation  is  too  large  for  over-all  efficiency. 

Mr.  Reynders.  I  am  not  taking  the  size  of  the  Corporation  par- 
ticularly, because  that  is  something  in  being,  but  for  the  perspective 
of  this  committee,  having  raised  the  question  at  all,  I  think  there  should 
be  on  the  part  of  one  who  is  so  experienced  as  you  are  in  the  industry, 
the  ability  to  indicate  what  would  be  a  reasonable  size  of  a  steel  enter- 
prise. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Well,  I  should  say  there  that  the  reasonable  size 
of  any  integrated  steel  plant  is  so  large  in  my  estimation  that  even  if 
you  broke  up  all  of  these  corporations  into  those  sizes,  the  number  of 
sellers  would  be  so  small  in  the  market  that  each  one  would  have  to 
take  into  consideration  liis  full  effect  upon  his  rivals.  If  that  gives 
you  an  answer  without  putting  a  dollar  figure  to  it^in  other  words,  I 
feel  that  the  fmidamental  conditions  in  the  industry  require  size. 
Wlien  a  continuous  mill  alone  requires  an  investment  of  from  twelve 
to  twenty-five  million  dollars,  when  blast  furnaces  require  an  invest- 
ment of  around  four  and  a  half  to  five  milUons,  when  your  steel  fur- 
naces require  an  investment  of  upward  of  $600,000 — that  is,  any 
integrated  firm  is  hkely  to  have  a  very  large  investment  and  is  likely 
to  be  a  very  large  plant.  Now,  whether  the  actual  size  of  a  plant  is  in 
excess  of  efficiency,  I  am  not  qualified  to  make  a  statement. 

Mr.  Reynders.  Well,  there  is  one  question:  You  would  regard  it  as 
necessary  to  have  diversification  of  products,  that  is,  you  couldn't  con- 
template a  steel  plant  that  devotes  itself  to  nothing  but  structural  or 
nothing  but  plates  or  nothing  but  tubes? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  I  could  not  contemplate  an  integrated  plant  which 
confines  itself  to  a  single  product.  The  investment  is  too  large  to 
locate  itself  with  relation  to  any  given  market  or  any  given  product. 
The  operating  characteristics  of  blast  furnaces  and  steel-making 
furnaces  require  something  close  to  capacity  operation  while  they  are 
in  operation,  and  therefore,  in  order  to  get  a  balance  of  utilization  over 
good  years  and  bad  and  with  shifts  m  demand,  you  need  a  multiplica- 
tion of  rolling  facihties.  For  that  reason,  although  you  may  establish 
a  nonintegrated  firm  close  to  a  given  market,  or  even  possibly  a  semi- 
integrated  firm,  I  doubt  whether  it  is  possible  to  locate  a  fully  inte- 
grated firm  with  relation  to  a  given  product  market. 

Mr.  Reynders.  Well,  getting  down  to  figures,  and  what  diversifi- 
cation of  products  means,  you  are  familiar  with  what  is  the  annual 
output  of  a  continuous  mill  layout  today? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Well,  of  course,  it  varies  with  the  mill.  A  flat 
rolled  production  of  output,  capacity  output,  up  to  800,000  tons — 
some  of  them  are  reported  even  up  to  a  million  tons. 

Mr.  Reynders.  Now,  such  a  plant,  running  to  capacity,  would  re- 
quire from  800,000  to  a  million  tons  of  ingots,  wouldn't  it? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  It  would  probably  require  more  because  of  con- 
version losses. 


13674       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Mr.  Reynders.  Yes.  Now,  if  you  add  to  that,  for  instance,  a 
structural  layout,  structural  and  plates,  those  two  items  together 
would  be  about  the  same  capacity  as  the  one  of  the  continuous  mill? 

Dr.  deChazeau.  What  you  mean  by  structural,  I  take  it,  is  a  roll- 
ing mill  for  shapes? 

Mr,  Reynders.  I-beams,  especially  the  broad  flange  beams 

Dr.  deChazeau  (interposing).  You  don't  mean  a  fabricating  unit? 

Mr.  Reynders.  Oh,  no;  entirely  rolled  products. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Well,  now  you  are  getting  into  a  field  in  which 
it  seems  to  me  there  are  men  present  here  who  are  better  qualified 
to  testify.  I  cannot.  It  is,  after  all,  a  fairly  well-known  fact  as  to 
what  the  range  hi  cost  iu  a  contuiuous  mill  is.  When  you  get  me 
down  to  special  mills,  I  am  not  prepared  to  quote  you  a  dollar  figure. 

Mr.  Reynders.  I  am  only  leading  up  to  what  the  reasonable  size 
of  the  steel  plant  is,  and  that  is,  I  think,  something  which  this  com- 
mittee is  very  much  interested  in.  I  am  merely  bringing  up  the 
various  items  because  they  are  simple,  extremely  simple,  and  I  think 
you  will  find  that  if  you"  wish  to  diversify,  iucluding  structural  ma- 
terial and  plates,  you  will  have  a  gain  of  about  600,000  tons  of  an- 
nual capacity,  •  and  no  plant  of  that  kind  would  operate  unless  they 
had  a  barn  which  would  hold  several  hundred  thousand,  tons.  Then 
you  have  the  category  of  pipe  and  wire,  which*  together  might  mean 
a  half  nullion  tons.  If  you  idd  those  together  you  have  something  of 
the  order  of  1,000,000,  wel  over  a  million  tons  of  finished  products, 
perhaps  a  million  and  a  qi:  .rter,  in  fact  much  more  than  that — I  beg 
yoiu"  pardon,  it  is  really  up  to  3,000,000  tons  when  I  add  up  these 
various  figures.  That,  then,  would  be  necessary  if  you  had  a 
diversified  organization. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  But  those  figures  are  probably  very  excessive,  as 
indicated  by  the  much  lower  capacity  of  Lutegrated  mills  such  as 
Inland's  mill  in  Chicago,  or  National  Steel. 

Mr.  Reynders.  Inland's  is  about  the  size  I  am  talking  about. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Yes.     I  haven't  the  figures  before  me. 

Mr.  Reynders.  I  can  figure  that;  they  are  probably  the  size. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  But  it  comes  to  a  large  figure.  It  is  in  the  order 
of  a  million. 

Mr.  -Reynders.  That  is  the  point  I  wanted  to  bring  out.  I  had 
3,000,000  tons  here  for  the  plant  that  I  have  outlined,  and  that  is 
about  the  size  of  Inland.     I  think  there  is  Youngstown  Sheet  &'  Tube. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  Is  that  total  finished  roUed  capacity  or  the  ingot 
capacity? 

Mr.  Reynders.  That  is  the  ingot  capacity.  That  is  the  common 
divisor.  I  think  that  Youngstown  Sheet  &  Tube  is  about  the 
same  size  as  Jones  &  Laughlin,  so  it  would  seem  to  me  perfectly  proper 
to  have  on  record  here  that  a  concern  of  about  that  size  is  not  un- 
reasonable; that  is,  when  you  are  talking  about  units  and  diversified 
units,  you  would  reach  some  such  size  as  we  have  here,  and  on  the 
basis  of  a  reconstruction  of  cost  today,  if  you  know  what  that  would 
be  for  a  ton,  annual  capacity. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  No;  there, are  men  better  qualified  to  give  you 
that  figure,  but  I  would  like  to  make  this  comment:  In  terms  of  the 
actual  development  of  mills  you  have  reached  that  capacity.  Whether 
that  capacity  constitutes  the  minimum  wliich  is  possible  with  efficient 
operations  docs  not  remain  clear,  or  rather  is  not  proved,  and  that  is 
why  I  hesitate  to  comment  completely  on  those  figures.     I  should 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EXX>NOMIC  POWER  13675 

suggest,  however,  that  the  mere  order  of  size  in  individual  plants  and 
integrated  groups,  assuming  that  businessmen  are  interested  in 
eflficiency  and  increasing  their  profits  through  efficiency,  would  indicate 
that  the  order  of  size  is  large,  but  I  wouldn't  comment  on  a  3,000,- 
000-ton  or  a  2,000,000-ton  or  even  a  1,000,000-ton  size  without  much 
more  data  than  I  have  available. 

Mr.  Reynders.  There  is  another  element  that  enters  into  this, 
Dr.  deChazeau,  and  that  is  geographical  distribution  and  geograph- 
ical markets  to  be  reached.  A  plant  of  the  kind  indicated  here,  if 
located  in  one  particular  locality,  would  of  course  have  restricted 
markets  and  even  going  to  this  size  you  are  still  to  an  extent  a  local 
concern,  not  covering  the  entire  area  of  the  United  States. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  May  I  say  in  connection  with  that  that  our  study 
of  the  distribution  of  products  will  throw  considerable  light  on  that 
relation  of  markets  to  given  producing  areas ;  although  it  will  not  give 
a  conclusive  answer  to  the  question,  it  will  at  least  throw  hght  on  the 
actual  distribution  from  a  given  producing  area. 

Mr.  Reynders.  My  object  here  was  to  have  in  the  record  and  for 
the  benefit  of  the  committee  an  adequate  idea  as  to  what  size  really 
constitutes  and  what  it  means  in  the  steel  industry.  This  type  of 
plant,  if  constructed  on  today's  prices,  would  be  of  the  order  of  about 
a  himdred  dollars  a  ton,  and  that  would  then  reach  the  size  of  about 
$300,000,000. 

Dr.  deChazeau.  That  is  right. 

Mr.  Reynders.  That  was  what  I  had  in  mind,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Mr.  Wooden.  I  have  a  question  I  shQuld  like  to  ask  of  Dr.  Yntema. 
Doctor,  do  you  think  any  clear  or  accurate  conclusion  can  be  drawn 
as  to  the  feasibihty  of  a  reduction  in  steel  prices  based  upon  a  cost 
study  which  includes  the  cost  of  such  things  as  cement,  the  operation 
of  common  carriers,  and  the  operation  of  coal  mines? 

Dr.  Yntema.  After  all,  the  operation  of  the  coal  mines  when  the 
coal  is  used  in  the  production  of  steel  is  just  as  much  a  part  of  steel 
production  as  the  processes,  nearer  the  final  products. 

With  reference  to  the  operations  of  the  railroads,  insofar  as  they 
carry  the  products  used  in  the  making  of  steel,  they  are  part  of  the 
steel-making  processes. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Insofar  as  they  are  common  carriers? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  insofar  as  they  carry  the  products  used  in  the 
aaking  of  the  steel,  they  are  part  of  the  integrated  steel  process. 

•  Mr.  Wooden.  And  what  about  cement? 

Dr.  Yntema.  In  the  case  of  cement  you  have  another  industry. 
I  am  not  famihar  with  the  technological  development  there.  I  i^der- 
stand  that  the  cement  plants  do  to  some  extent  use  a  byproduct  of  the 
steel  industry,  but  the  poiut  that  is  relevant,  I  thihk,  is  that  the  total 
operations  of  the  cement  plants  are  scarcely  a  drop  in  the  bucket  in 
comparison  with  the  other  items  It  wouldn't  vitiate  any  findings 
which  I  presented  here. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  It  is  important  to  have  iron  ore  too,  is 
it  not? 

Dr.  Yntema.  it  is.  necessary  in  integrated  operations,  of  course. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  In  the  production  of  steel.  Would  there 
be  any  objection  to  a  steel  company  obtaining  not  only  its  coal  supply 
but  its  iron-ore  supply  as  a  part  of  its  integrated  activity?  Would 
that  not  make  it  perhaps  to  the  advantage  of  the  consumer  ultimately? 

124491— 41— pt.  26 7 


13676  coNCEN;rRATiON  of  economic  power 

Dr.  Yntema.  Let  me  say  with  reference  to  questions  of  this  type 
that  I  am  not  a  steel  man  and  I  am  not  competent  to  speak  on  ques- 
tions of  integration.  I  simply  made  a  study  of  some  phases  of  this 
subject.  I  do  not  wish  to  commit  myself  on  matters  outside  my 
knowledge. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  The  committee  will  take  a  recess  until 
2  o'clock. 

(Whereupon,  at  12:25  p.  m.,  the  committee  recessed  until  2  p.  m. 
of  the  same  day.) 

AFTERNOON    SESSION 

The  hearing  was  resumed  at  2  p.  m.  upon  the  expiration  of  the  recess- 
Acting  Chairman  King.  Are  you  read)'^? 

Dr.  Kreps.  Yes. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  The  committee  will  be  in  order. 

Call  your  first  witness. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Dr.  Mordecai  Ezekiel. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Come  forward,  please.  Doctor,  will  you 
hold  up  your  right  hand?  Do  you  solemnly  swear  that  the  evidence 
you  shall  give  in  this  hearing  shall  be  the  truth,  the  whole  truth,  and 
nothing  but  the  truth,  so  help  you  God? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  I  do. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  State  your  name  and  residence. 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Mordecai  Ezekiel,  Washington,  D.  C. 

TESTIMONY  OF  DR.  MORDECAI  EZEKIEL,  ECONOMIC  ADVISER 
TO  THE  SECRETARY,  DEPARTMENT  OF  AGRICULTURE,  WASH- 
INGTON, D.  C. 

Dr.  Kreps.  What  position  do  you  hold.  Dr.  Ezekiel? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  I  am  economic  adviser  to  the  Secretary  of  Agriculture. 

Dr.  Kreps.  But  as  I  un'derstand  it,  you  are  appearing  in  no  respect 
as  a  representative  of  the  Department  of  Agriculture,  but  only  as  an 
expert  on  statistical  and  economic  matters,  particularly  on  price 
analysis? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  That  is  correct.  I  am  not  appiCaring  for  the  Depart- 
ment, but  am  appearing  as  an  expert  in  statistical  and  economic 
analysis. 

Dr.  Kreps.  How  long  an  experience  have  you  had  in  the  tech- 
niques of  statistical  Research  employed  here  by  the  Steel  Corporation? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  I  have  been  working  approximately  20  years  using 
these  methods,  and  have  a  textbook,  Methods  of  Correlation  Analysis, 
which  presents  most  of  the  methods  Dr.  Yntema  has  used. 

'Dr.  Kreps.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  it  is  a  standard  reference  work  in 
this  field.  Tl^ese  methods  were  first  applied  in  what  field.  Dr. 
Ezekiel? 

Dr.  Ezekiel,  The  methods  have  been  used  very  widely  in  the  field 
of  agriculture,  particularly  in  the  economic  analysis  of  changes  in 
prices  and  production  of  farm  products,  in  the  Bureau  of  Agricultural 
Economics  jind  agricultural  colleges  throughout  the  country. 

Dr.  Kreps.  And  have  you  utilized  these  methods  in  your  economic 
analyses  concerning  what  might  stimulate  employment  and  the  like? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Yes,  I  have  used  them  to  some  extent  in  industry. 
They  have  been  applied  inuch  less  in  industry,  however,  than  they 


CX)NCENTRATION  OF  ECX)NOivIIC  POWER  13677 

have  in  agriculture.  I  have  given  a  good  deal  of  attention  also  to 
the  general  problem  of  unemployment  and  to  the  steps  that  industry 
might  take  in  dealing  with  the  problem  of  unemployment  and  low 
production. 

Dr.  Keeps.  In  that  connection,  it  seems  to  me  I  remember  two 
books  of  which  you  are  the  author,  one  entitled  "Twenty -five  Hundred 
Dollars  A  Year,"  and  the  other,  "Jobs  For  All." 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  That  is  correct.  I  have  two  recent  books  on  the 
general  subject  of  correcting  industrial  unemployment. 

ANALYSIS  OF  DR.  YNTEMA's  STATEMENT  CONCERNING  PRICES,   VOLUME, 
COSTS,    AND    PROFITS 

Dr.  Kreps.  Would  you  care  to  comment  on  the  general  significance 
of  the  results  which  Dr.  Yntema  has  secured  in  which  he  has  utilized 
your  methods  and  their  bearing,  as  you  see  it,  on  the  general  problem 
of  unemployment? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Yes,  that  is  what  I  am  now  prepared  to  do. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  have  a  statement,  have  you? 

Dr.  Ea^KiEL.  Yes,  I  have  a  statement  summarizing  my  views  on 
these  points. 

The  material  that  Dr.  Yntema  presented  may  be  summarized  jn 
three  broad  statements: 

First,  that  if  the  steel  industry  were  to  reduce  its  prices  at  any 
time,  the  percentage  gain  in  sales  (due  solely  to  the  reduction  in 
price)  would  be  at  most  no  greater  th^n  the  percentage  reduction  in 
price,  so  that  in  consequence  the  gross  income  of  the  steel  industry 
would  show  no  increase  as  a  result  of  the  price  reduction. 

Second,  if  the  sales  of  steel  were  to  increase  at  any  time,  the  larger 
output  would  lead  to  a  reduction  in  production  costs  per  ton,  but 
those  costs  per  unit  would  not  fall  as  rapidly  as  output  rose,  so  that 
total  costs  would  increase  as  sales  rose. 

Third,  that  reduction  in  price  would  always  reduce  the  profits  or 
increase  the  deficits  of  the  Corporation.  That  result  follows  from 
his  argument,  since  total  income  would  not  increase  with  the  increased 
sales,  whereas  total  costs  would  increase. 

I  have  been  over  rather  carefully  the  statistical  technics  used  both 
in  the  cost  analysis  and  in  the  price  analysis,  and  there  are  ^  good 
many  individual  weaknesses  in  technic.  Other  witnesses  will  discuss 
the  detail  weaknesses  in  the  statistical  analysis  made.  The  points 
that  I  am  going  to  take  up  here  are  not  differences  of  analysis,  but 
the  interpretation  made  of  the  results  obtained.  What  I  piopose  to 
show  is  that  even  for  the  time  accepting  the  results  of  the  analysis  in 
the  Steel  Corporation  documents,  that  the  conclusions  they  draw  from 
those  results  do  not  necessarily  follow. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Do  you  mean  to  state  that  the  factors 
which  they  have  taken  into  account  do  not  exist  or  that  they  have 
placed  too  much  stress  upon  one  factor  and  too  little  upon  another? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  No,  I  am  accepting  for  the  time  their  measurement 
of  the  effect  of  a  change  in  price  on  quantity  sold  as  measured  by  their 
statistical  analysis,  but  I  shall  draw  attention  to  the  fact  that  there 
arei  other  concurrent  elements  in  their  analysis  which  they  have 
ignored   in-    their    subsequent    interpretation.     Even    though   their 


13678       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

statistical  analysis  is  taken  as  correct,  the  conclusions  they  reach  are 
not  necessarily  the  right  conclusions. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  don't  mean  to  state  that  those  in 
charge  of  the  business,  interested,  of  course,  as  they  are  in  its  develop- 
ment and  in  the  protection  of  the  capital  invested  and  of  the  labor  that 
is  involved,  you  do  not  mean  to  state  that  they  do  not  try  to  ascertain 
the  material  condition,  if  I  may  use  that  expression,  the  utiUtarian 
outlook,  and  then  adjust  their  business  to  meet  the  situation,  the  rise 
in  prices  or  the  decline  in  the  market,  in  the  consumptive  demands 
and  so  on? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  I  am  not  criticizing  at  all  the  technics  of  the  industry 
as  it  has  operated.  As  I  understand  it,  in  fact  the  industry  has  oper- 
ated to  tins  time  without  having  these  research  results.  These  re- 
search results  have  just  been  worked  out  and  apparently,  therefore, 
are  something  different  from  the  practical  basis  upon  which  the  in- 
dustry is  operating.  I  am  taking  the  research  material  which  is  in- 
troduced as  testimony  to  show  that  the  industry  had  been  justified  in 
not  following  a  lower  price  policy  and  am  reanalyzing  the  material  to 
show  how  quite  different  conclusions  can  be  reached  from  the  same 
material. 

The  statement  that  they  made,  that  it  would  never  pa^  to  reduce 
prices,  rests  upon  three  assumptions  that  are  made  in  their  analysis, 
two  of  which  were  not  expHcitly  stated  in  Dr.  Yntema's  presentation 
or  in  the  document  submitted.  Those  assumptions  are  these:  First, 
that  a  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel,  while  it  might  increase  soiflewhat 
the  quantity  of  steel  sold,  would  have  absolutely  no  effect  on  the  gen- 
eral level  of  business  activity. 

Second,  that  reductions  in  the  price  of  steel  would  have  no  effect 
upon  tlie  level  of  prices  involved  in  the  cost  of  producing  steel. 

Third,  that  there  is  no  possibility  of  bringing  about  concerted  action 
by  the  steel  industry  and  other  industries  by  which  not  only  steel 
prices  but  prices  of  many  other  products  could  all  be  reduced  at  the 
same  time,  so  as  to  get  a  much  larger  stimulus  to  activity  than  could 
be  produced  from  the  effect  of  reducing  steel  prices  alone. 

Dr.  Yntema  referred  'briefly  to  this  third  point  yesterday,  but  not 
to  the  other  two.  . 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  wouldn't  mean  by  tha,t  that  there 
ought  to  be  sort  of  a  combination  between  the  steel  industry  and 
others  with  a  view  to  raising  or  lowering  prices? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  That  is  the  point  I  will  discuss  toward  the  end  of 
my  statement. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Running  perhaps  head-on  with  the  Fed- 
eral Trade  Commission  or  with  the  Sherman  antitrust  law.  You  are 
not  advocating  that,  I  assume. 

Dr.  F^ZEKiEL.  Toward  the  end  of  my  statement  I  discuss  that  point, . 
so  if  you  will  permit  me,  I  will  put  it  off  until  I  come  to  it. 

Taking  up  each  of  these  three  points  separately,  the  first  is  as  to 
the  assumption  made  on  the  price  of  steel.  The  statistical  method 
.used  in  determining  the  over-all  effect  of  a  price  reduction  on  the 
q^uantity  of  steel  sold  is  the  method  that  is  known  as  multiple  correla- 
tion analysis,  a  method  by  which  you  examine  the  simultaneous  results 
of  several  different  factors  all  affecting  another  factor.  By  that 
method  it  has  beeil  determined  that  the  year-to-year  changes  in  steel 
output  and  sales  in  the  period  since  the  first  World  War  have  been 


^     CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13679 

explained  largely  by  three  factors.  The  first  of  those  factors  is  the 
level  of  industrial  activity,  or  the  level  of  industrial  profits  and  of' 
national  income.  The  second  factor  is  the  price  of  steel,  and  the  third 
factor  is  the  long-time  trend  in  the  demand  for  steel. 

Now,  in  measuring  the  effect  of  changes  in  each  one  of  those  factors 
on  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  or  shipped,  the  analysis  assumes  Ihat 
only  one  factor  is  permitted  to  change  at  any  one  time  while  all  the 
others  are  held  constant.  That  is,  they  have  measured  how  much 
change  there  would  be  in  steel  sales,  if  the  price  of  steel  was  either 
increas3d  or  decreased,  while  business  ac'vity  did  not  change  and 
while  the  trend  factor  was  held  constant,  and  then  they  have  measured 
how  much  a  change  in  business  activity  would  affect  the  sales  of 
steel,  if  meanwhile  prices  were  held  constant  and  trend  were  held 
constant. 

From  that  statistical  analysis  the  conclusion  has  been  reached  that 
if  the  steel  prices  were  reduced  but  the  other  factors  were  held  con- 
stant, with  no  change  in  business  activity  and  no  change  ia  trend, 
that  at  best  sales  would  increase  no  more  rapidly  than  the  price  fell 
in  percentage  terms.  That  is  what  the  elasticity  of  not  more  than 
one  means.  But  that  conclusion  in  their  analysis  holds  true  only  if 
it  were  possible  for  steel  prices  to  be  reduced  while  industrial  activity 
meanwhile  remained  unchanged. 

I  want  to  consider  for  a  moment  \/hat  does-  actually  happen  when 
steel  prices  are  changed.  Assume,  for  example,  U.  S.  Steel  Corpora- 
tion would  reduce  its  price,  and  as  a  result  of  its  reduced  price  increase 
its  production  and  sales  as  they  have  shown.  Not  merely  U.  S.  Steel 
would  reduce  its  price  and  output,  but  all  the  other  steel  companies 
would  reduce  their  price  and  increase  their  production  and  sales. 
As  a  matter  of  fact,  the  analysis  they  present  is  not  the  analysis  of 
the  tuect  of  price  on  U.  S.  Steel  sales,  but  is  an  analysis  of  the  effect 
of  price  on  sales  of  the  entire  industry.  As  a  result  of  producing 
more  steel,  they  employ  more  men,  they  buy  more  materials,  and  they 
pay  more  for  the  costs  of  the  industry,  so  the  disbursements  for  the 
whole  great  steel  industry  for  wages,  material,  power  and  freight, 
would  rise.  Not  only  would  disbursements  in  the  steel  industry 
rise,  but  more  steel  being  produced  and  purchased  would  mean  that 
more  steel  was  being  used  in  automobiles  and  construction,  con- 
tainers, machine  tools,  and  all  the  other  various  uses.  So  that  would 
mean  these  other  industries  would  also  be  employing  more  men,  be 
increasing  their  pay  rolls,  be  shipping  more  products  and  increasing 
their  disbursements.  As  steel  production  increases,  that  carries  with 
it  a  change  in  the  production  of  all  other,  industries.  Their  assump- 
tion has  been  that  all  the  time  while  the  price  of  steel  was  reduced, 
industrial  activity  has  been  unchanged,  while  only  the  price  reduc- 
tions affected  steel  sales. 

I  have  brought  with  me  a  chart  which  shows  how  absurd  it  is  to 
assume  that  steel  output  could  change  without  a  corresponding  change 

in  the  level  of  industrial  activities  as  a  whole.    This  chart 

~    Dr.  Keeps  (interposing).  Dr.  Ezekiel,  for  the  purpose  of  identifi- 
cation, would  you  like  to  have  this  chart  introduced  into  the  record? 
Dr.  Ezekiel.  Yes;  I  would. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Mr.  Chairmaii,  I  should  like  to  offer  this  chart,  en- 
titled, "Relation  of  Industrial  Production,  Excluding  Iron  9,nd  Steel, 
to  Steel  Sales,"  for  the  record. 


13680  CONCENTRATION  OF  t\?ONOMIC  POWER 

Acting  Chairman  King.  It  may  be  admitted,  without  objection. 
(The  chart  referred  to  was  marked  "Exhibit  No.  2183"  and  is 
included  in  the  appendix  on  p.  14119.) 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  What  this  fehart  shows  is  the  relation  of  changes 
in  steel  shipments  year  by  year  to  changes  in  the  level  of  industrial 
activity.  The  way  the  chart  is  prepared  is  this:  Each  year  is  repre- 
sented by  a  single  dot  and  that  dot  is  placed  both  according  to  the 
million  tons  of  steel  shipped  that  year,  and  according  to  the  industrial 
production  excluding  iron  and  steel;  that  is,  according  to  the  index 
of  industrial  production  in  industries  other  than  the  steel  industry. 

Now,  starting  with  a  couple  of  low  years  after  the  War,  thereafter 
there  is  a  very  consistent  relation  between  changes  in  steel  shipments 
and  changes  in  the  level  of  activity  in  other  industries.  Every  single 
time  that  there  was  an  increase  in  steel  output,  there  is  an  increase 
in  the  activity  of  the  other  industries.  For  example,  here  from  1932 
to  1933,  steel  shipments  increased  from  around  a  little  over  10,000,000 
tons  to  about  16,000,000  tons,  activity  in  the  other  industries  in- 
creased from  about  73  to  82. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Dr.  Ezekiel,  if  you  had  limited  yourself  to  the  same 
period  as  Dr.  Yntema  limited  his  analysis  the  dots  for  1920  and  1921 
would  not  appear;  isn't  that  correct? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Yes.     Those  years  were, not  used  in  his  cost  analysis. 
Dr.  Kreps.  Then  the  conformance  of  the  dots  to  the  line  would 
be  considerably  closer;  is  that  correct? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Yes.  You  can  see,  except  for  those  3  years,  how 
closely  all  the  other  dots  adhere  to  the  line,  showing  the  average 
relation  between  change  in  steel  sales,  steel  shipments  and  a  change 
in  the  general  level  of  activity  in  industries  other  than  steel. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  May  we  not  postulate  increase  in  steel 
resulted  from  the  increase  in  the  other  activities,  instead  of  the 
steel  being  the  motivating,  the  moving  cause,  that  the  other  industries 
and  activities  were  the  ones,  and  they  had  their  influence  upon  steel 
and  caused  the  increase  or  rise  in  steel? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  So  far  as  the  figures  presented  in  the  chart  are  con- 
cerned, they  do  not  tell  us  which  is  cause  and  which  is  effect.  It 
could  be  as  you  suggest,  either  way. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  don't  intend  to  say  that  steel  is  the 
lever  which  determines  the  rise  or  the  fall  of  the  business  activities^, 
industrial  activities,  of  our  country? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  No,  I  am  not  saying  that  steel  is  the  sole  cause  of 
changes  in  business  activity,  but  the  point  that  I  am  making  is  that 
changes  in  steel  production  and  changes  in  activitv  in  industries 
other  than  steel  are  so  closely  associated  that  regardless  of  which  is 
cause  and  which  is  effect,  we  have  not  in  fact  had  changes  in  one  with- 
out changes  in  the  other.  So  that  to  assume  that  you  could  make  a 
material  increase  in  steel  production  without  at  the  same  time  having 
material  increase  in  otlier  industries,  is  to  go  against  the  record  of  the 
past  period. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Wo  have  been  led  to  believe  by  some  of 
the  earnest  and  sincere  and  intelligent  advocates  of  agriculture  that 
agriculture  was  the  principal,  the  most  important,  industry  and  that 
the  condition  of  the  farmers  determines  the  condition  of  the  rest  of 
our  economic  life;  that  if  agriculture  was  prosperous,  everything  would 
be  prosperous,  including  the  steel  industry.     You  are  not  trying  to 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13681 

minimize  the  importanee  of  agriculture,  you  being  in  the  Agricultural 
Department? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  It  is  true  there  as  here,  that  large  demand  for 
agricultural  or  farm  products  is  associated  with  high  buying  power 
in  the  cities,  and  high  buying  power  on  the  farm  in  turn  helps  main- 
tain city  activity.  But  there,  as  here,  there  are  two  factors  that  run 
together,  and  saying  which  one  is  cause  and  which  one  is  effect,  well, 
all  one  can  say  is  that  they  do  move  up  and  they  do  move  down 
together. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Dr.  Ezekiel,  for  purposes  of  removing  all  elements  of, 
shall  I  say,  obfuscation,  concerning  this  chart,  is  there  anything 
technically  that  can  be  said  against  this  chart  that  is  not  equally 
true  of  the  other  chart;  that  is  Dr.  Yntema's  chart  is  taken  to  prove 
that  the  prosperity  of  the  steel  industry  is  dependent  on  industrial 
production,  such  an  inference  stands  or  falls  on  the  same  anah^tical 
and  statistical  grounds  as  this  chart;  if  one  is  admissible,  the  other  is 
admissible,  and  if  one  is  not  admissible,  neither  is  admissible? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Yes.  The  type  of  analysis  is  the  same  here  as  there, 
that  we  are- reasoning  from  the  fact  that  certain  variables  move  or  do 
not  move  together. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  There  may  be  some  industries  though  that 
are  prosperous,  profitable,  whereas  other  industries  are  not  pros- 
perous, o^-er  the  same  period? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Well,  this  chart,  of  course,  does  not  attempt  to 
measure  profits.  It  simply  takes  the  observed  facts  as  to  volume  of 
output  and  says  that  the  record  shows  that  when  there  is  a  large 
volume  of  steel  output,  there  is  also  a  large  volume  of  output  in  other 
industries;  when  there  is  a  low  volume  of  steel  output,  there  has 
always  been  a  low  volume  of  output  in  other  industries.  It  does  not 
go  beyond  that  point. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Well,  does  not  the  increased  output  in 
other  industries  lead  to  an  increased  output  in  steel? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Opinions  can  differ  on  that.  I  believe,  however, 
that  the  record  will  show  that  the  changes  in  steel  production  have 
been  more  responsible  for  changes  in  the  total  of  industrial  activity 
than  have  the  changes  in  most  other  industries;  that  steel  production 
is  more  variable  than  the  total  output  of  other  industries;  and  that 
the  heavy  capital  goods,  such  as  steel,  may  play  a  predominant  part 
in  the  business  cycle.  For  example,  the  output  of  agricultural  pro- 
ducts varies  only  10  or  15  percent  from  high  to  low,  whereas  the  output 
of  steel  during  the  same  period  has  varied  from  as  low  as  10,000,000 
tons  to  as  high  as  35,000,000  tons. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Well,  I  can't  help  but  believe  that  the 
prosperit;^  of  agriculture  determines  in  part  at  least  the  prosperity  of 
the  steel  industry.  I  recall  when  a  boy,  working  on  the  farm,  when 
our  products,  farm  pioducts,  brought  a  good  price,  we  would  buy 
more  wagons  and  more  reapers,  more  mowers,  and  more  steel  com- 
modities which  we  used  in  connection  with  agricultui-al  development, 
and  the  purchase  of  those  steel  commodities,  of  course,  furnished  an 
additional  market  for  the  steel  industry,  so  that  the  steel  industry 
prospered  when  we  prospered;  that  is  to  say,  their  output  increased 
when  our  output  of  agricultural  commodities  had  a  reasonable  price 


13682       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

I  don't  know  which  was  the  chicken  and  which  was  the  egg  there, 
but  I  know  that  the  prosperity  of  the  farmers  brought  prosperity  to 
other  branches,  including  the  steel  industry,  and  I  cannot  quite  con- 
ceive of  the  theory  that  the  s'teel  industry  is  the  lever  that  moves  our 
entire  economic  and  industrial  fabric. 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Well,  if  you  will  pardon  me,  sir,  I  am  not  trying  to 
say  that  it  is  the  sole  lever,  but  I  am  trying  to  say  that  it  is  one  of  the 
levers.  It  is  quite  true,  as  you  state,  that  when  farmers  have  income 
and  can  buy  more  tractors  and  more  automobiles,  that  helps  the 
demand  for  steel,  but  it  is  also  true  that  only  a  relatively  small  pro- 
portion of  steel  goes  into  such  uses,  as  compared  to  the  total  amount 
of  stegl  going  into  railroad  cars  and  the  construction  industry  and  all 
the  many  other  industrial  uses  of  steel,  as  well  as  farm  machinery  and 
the  farm  portion  of  automobiles. 

Acting  Chf».irman  King.  That  would   mean,   of   course,    that   the 
railroad  industry,  which  has  been  one  of  the  largest  consumers  of  steel, 
when  it  is  prosperous,  it  adds  to  the  prosperity  of  the  steel  industry? 
Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Quite  So. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  And  if  the  railroad  industry  is  in  the 
doldrums,  as  it  has  been  for  a  number  of  years,  in  part  due  to  the 
development  of  trucks,  waterways,  and  other  means  of  transporta- 
tion, it  affects  quite  materially  the  profits  and  business  of  the  steel 
industry. 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  The  sc<e  point  I  am  making  at  this  time  is  that  if  a 
reduction  in  steel  prices  does  increase  the  quantity  of  steel  sold,  that 
means  more  products  are  being  hauled  over  the  railroad,  more  steel 
is  being  used,  and  there  is  an  associated  increase  in  other  industries. 
That  is  as  far  as  I  am  going  at  the  moment. 

Mr.  HiNRipHS.  Your  materials  here  are  essentially  the  same  as  the 
materials  that  Dr.  Yntema  presented  when  he  mentioned  the  relation- 
ship between  industrial  activity  and  steel  output,  and  you  are  merely 
calling  attention  to  tl ».  fact  that  by  virtue  of  the  fact  that  a  change  in 
steel  price  stimulates  to  some  extent  volume  of  business,  there  is  a 
secondary  reaction,  so  that  if  his  figure  of  three-tenths  of  a  percent 
were  to  be  taken  as  correct  it  would  inevitably  be  somewhat  larger 
than  that,  you  are  not  saying  how  much  larger  at  this  stage  of  the 
game,  but  that  there  must  be  some  addition  beyond  the  thing  that 
comes  from  the  processes  that  Mr.  Yntema  used  by  virtue  of  this 
repercussion  from  the  stimulated  industrial  activity.  Is  that  correct? 
Dr.  EzEKiEL.  That  is  the  point  to  which  I  am  now  coming.  For 
these  statistical  purposes  it  is  very  convenient  to  measure  the  separate 
effects  of  business  activity  and  of  steel  prices  on  the  amount  ot  steel 
production  and  shipments,  but  after  that  has  been  done  it  is  quite 
erroneous  to  assume  that  you  can  reduce  steel  prices  and  increase 
steel  sales  without  at  the  same  time  increasing  business  activity. 

The  analysis  that  w^-s  presented  in  the  documents  in  Dr.  Yntema's 
statement  yesterday  indicated  that  cbanges  in  business  activity  wei^ 
about  10  times  as  important  as  were  changes  in  prices,  in  accounting 
for  changes  in  steel  production.  The  tables  in  his  statistical  analysis 
show  that  the  percent  of  the  variation  in  steel  consumption  explained 
by  business  activity  was  of  a  magnitude  about  10  times  as  great  as 
the  percent  of  the  variation  explained  by  steel  prices.  But  then  when 
he  came  to  estimate  how  much  mcrease  in  production  you  get  for 
rcd\!ctiou  m  price  he  took  into  account  only  the  eJect  of  price  on  sales 


OONCEKTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13683 

and  made  no  allowance  whatever  for  the  effect  of  the  associated 
increase  m  business  activity  on  steel,  so  that  in  considering  price 
alone  and  in  failing  to  consider  the  associated  changes  in  business 
activity,  the  analysis  presented  has  left  out  of  account  the  most 
important  single  factor.  In  consequence,  it  has  gravely  understated 
the  increase  in  sales  which  might  be  expected  to  follow  from  a  given 
reduction  in  price.  For  that  reason  it  is  quite  possible  that  a  reduc- 
tion in  steel  prices  would  cause  a  very  much  larger  increase  in  sales 
than  the  computations  presented  assumed,  and  it  is  therefore  likewise 
quite  possible  that  sales  would  increase  so  greatly  with  a  lower  level 
of  price  that  the  gross  income  of  steel  producers  would  rise  as  the 
price  of  steel  fell  or  was  reduced. 

The  second  weakness  in  the  analysis  lies  in  the  assumption  that 
the  price  level  of  the  factors  entering  into  steel  production  would 
remain  the  same  regardless  of  the  price  of  steel.  It  is  well  known,  for 
example,  that  steel  scrap  is  an  important  material  in  steel  production, 
and  it  is  also  customary  that  scrap  prices  and  pig  iron  prices  move 
fairly  closely  together,  so  that  cheaper  iron  and  steel  would  mean 
probably  less  expensive  scrap.  Furthermore,  the  analysis  of  costs 
presented  by  the  Steel  Corporation  took  into  account  the  wholesale 
price  level  as  one  of  the  factors  with  which  to  adjust  the  "other  costs" 
item  of  costs.  They  show  that  the  material  costs  move  with  the 
general  price  level.  Steel  and  iron  are  major  industrial  products, 
so  that  it  is  not  unreasonable  to  assume  that  changes  in  the  price  of 
steel  and  iron  may  exercise  a  price  leadership  not  only  on  steel  scrap 
but  throughout  many  industrial  prices.  As  a  matter'  of  fact,  the 
record  of  the  past  20  years  does  show  that  steel  prices  and  the  prices 
of  other  industrial  products  have  moved  together  quite  closely  through 
most  of  the  past  20  years,  have  had  very  similar  general  price  move- 
ments. So  to  the  extent  that  both  scrap  and  other  industrial  prices 
were  influenced  by  reductions  in  iron  and  steel  prices,  the  costs  of 
producing  steel  would  be  reduced,  at  least  relative  to  that  which  they 
have  shown.  So  even  assuming  the  accuracy  of  their  cdst  analysis,  it 
is  still  quite  possible  that  a  reduction  in  steel  prices  and  an  increase 
in  steel  output  would  cause  materially  less  increase  in  Corporation 
expenditures  than  their  calculations  have  shown.  You  see,  I  am  not 
criticizing  their  calculations;  I  am  cricitizing  their  failure,  in  estimating 
the  increase  in  total  cost  of  the  Corporation,  resulting  from  an  increase 
in  output,  to  take  into  account  that  the  lower  iron  and  steel  price  at 
which  they  output  was  produced  would  also  mean  lower  prices  for  some 
of  the  products  that  they  were  buying,  and  therefore  not  as  much 
increase  in  total  cost  as  they  have  shown,  based  upon  the  1938  level  of 
prices. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  That  is  to  say,  you  would  be  criticizing 
the  steel  management  for  not  producing  more  steel  when  they  got  down 
to  30  or  40  percent  of  their  capacity,  or  25  percent,  even  though  at  that 
time  they  couldn't  find  a  market  for  the  amount  of  steel  which  they 
were  producing  at  that  small  percentage  of  capacity.  You  think  they 
ought  to  have  continued  their  output,  even  tahave  lowered  the  prices," 
for  the  purpose  of  stimulating  activities  in  other  enterprises? 

Dr.  EzEKiFL.  What  I  am  considering  is,  had  they  lowered  their 
price,  how  much  of  an  increase  in  sales  that  would  have  made  and  how 
much  of  an  increase  in  total  costs  they  would  have  faced.  They  have 
presented  materials  which  show  that  had  they  lowered  their  price  they 


13684        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

would  not  have  increased  their  sales  any  more  than  they  reduced  the 
price,  so  they  would  not  have  increased  their  gross  income,  and  that 
tliey  would  have  increased  their  total  costs  materially  so  they  would 
have  lost  more  by  doing  it.  What  I  am  attempting  to  show  is  that 
their  analysis  of  their  own  data  does  not  necessarily  lead  to  that  con- 
clusion, that  they  have  left  out  of  account  certain  very  important 
factors,  first  on  the  demand  side  and  then  on  the  cost  side,  which  makes 
the  result  that  might  have  been  obtained  materially  different  from 
that  which  they  have  presented  to  you. 

Mr.  Walter  White.  On  the  demand  side,  Dr.  Ezekiel,  doesn't 
it  make  a  difference  whether  you  make  your  price  reduction  at  a  time 
when  industrial  activity  is  increasing  or  whether  you  make  it  at  a 
time  when  general  industrial  activity  may  be  static  or  declining? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  I  am  not  an  expert  in  the  steel  industry,  I  don't 
know  the  answer,  but  I  might  say  that  no  material  has  been  presented 
by  the  Corporation  to  show  that  there  is  such  a  difference.  The  fact 
that  they  have  never  tried  reducing  tbeir  prices  during  periods  of 
depression  to  see  if  they  could  move  more  material,  that  is,  reducing 
prices  in  the  magnitude  of  the  type  discussed  here,  means  we  don't 
have  any  experience  to  go  on.  We  do  know  in  the  field  of  agriculture 
that  when  farmers  reduce  tbeir  prices  very  greatly  they  can  as  a  result 
of  those  low  prices  move  into  consumption  just  as  much  as  they  moved 
into  consumption  before.  We  do  know  that  throughout  the  depres- 
sion except  when  the  drought  came  along,  farmers  continued  to  pro- 
duce almost  as  much  as  they  had  been  producing  before  and  moved 
into  consumption  that  continued  output. 

Actmg  Chairman  King.  Is  that  true  of  cotton? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Yes;  by  and  large  it  is  true  of  cotton.  Even  for 
cotton  the  very  low  prices  resulted  in  a  sustained  domestic  consump- 
tion of  cotton  from  1936  to  date  which  was  not  so  much  below  the 
predepression  levels. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  are  not  taking  into  account  the  mil- 
lions of  dollars  with  which  we  have  had  to  subsidize  the  cotton 
industry  by  reason  of  the  decline  in  the  consumptive  demands,  closing 
of  markets,  the  lack  of  demand  for  cotton. 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  The  greater  part  of  that  loss  of  consumption  was  in 
the  foreign  market  rather  than  the  domestic,  and  that  is  outside  of 
the  thing  I  was  trying  to  present  now. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Except  by  way  of  analogy.  If  I  had  time 
I  would  call  your  attention  to  the  dechne  in  the  production  of  zinc  and 
lead  and  copper  and  all  of  the  metals  during  the  period  when  the 
prices  went  down  until  copper  was  sold  at  4  and  5  cents  a  pound,  per- 
haps at  a  loss  of  4  or  5  cents  a  pound,  and  yet  with  those  low  prices 
it  didn't  stimulate  the  consumptive  demand  of  copper. 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  It  is  quite  true,  sir,  that  most  industries  have  oper- 
ated the  same  as  steel  has  operated,  and  that  is  the  precise  point  why 
this  question  of  industrial  price  poUcy  is  so  important,  because  it  is 
true  that  most  industries  follow  the  practice  of  maintaining  their 
prices  with  only  at  most  moderate  reductions.  You  mentioned  some 
that  reduced  more,  but  most  of  the  heavy  industries  did  not.  Auto- 
mobiles sold  in  '33  at  much  the  same  price  as  they  sold  in  '29,  and  they 
took  out  the  reduction  in  demand  in  a  greatly  reduced  output,  turning 
their  workers  out  into  the  street  to  take  care  of  themselves,  or  let  the 
Government  take  care  of  them.     Farmers  take  the  depression  in  low 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13685 

prices;  industry  takes  the  depression  in  low  employment  and  their 
workers  stay  idle. 

Dr.  Keeps.  I  am  not  sure  that  I  imderstand  you  correctly.  You 
don't  mean  to  say  that  there  has  not  been  a  reduction  in  absolute  steel 
prices  during  the  period  from  1929  to  1932,  do  you? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  No,  the  point  I  was  making  is  that  the  reduction  in 
price  has  been  very  small  contrasted  to  the  reduction  in  output,  and 
very  small  contrasted  to  the  reduction  in  the  prices  of  farm  products 
and  many  other  industrial  products. 

Dr.  Kreps.  When  we  speak  of  steel  prices  being  relatively  high,  we 
mean  relative  to  what? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Well,  it  depends  on  the  base  we  use.  We  may  say 
steel  prices  are  high  relative  to  1929,  or  we  may  say  they  are  high 
relative  to  other  products. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Wlien  you  said  that  the  steel  prices  did  not  dechne, 
that  we  had  no  experience  of  a  decline  in  steel  prices,  you  meant  no 
experience  of  a  decline  in  steel  prices  which  was  greater,  relatively, 
than  the  decline  in  prices  in  general? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  That  is  correct.  I  might  say  also  we  have  very  little 
experience  with  a  decUne  in  steel  prices  even  as  great  as  in  the  prices 
of  other  products. 

Dr.  Keeps.  In  general  it  is  true  that  steel  belongs  to  an  order  of 
producer's  goods  which  as  Dr.  Mills  has  pointed  out  in  a  three  volume 
analysis  rose  relatively  in  price  during  the  depression,  became  rela- 
tively more  expensive.     Is  that  correct? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Yes,  you  had  to  use  more  of  other  maferials  to  buy 
steel;  that  is,  a  ton  of  steel  in  1932  and  '33  cost  a  great  many  more 
bushels  of  wheat,  or  bushels  of  corn,  or  bales  of  cotton,  or  even  suits 
of  clothes,  than  it  did  in  1929. 

Dr.  Keeps.  And  that  is  the  important  point  for  the  problem  of 
investment,  and  the  Uke,  is  it  not? 

Dr.  EZEKiEii.  It  is  one  of  the  important  points;  I  wouldn't  say  it 
was  the  exclusive  one. 

I  have  considered  the  price  analysis  presented  and  the  cost  analysis 
presented,  and  I  have  shown  that  even  accepting  the  results  secured 
by  the  accounting  and  statistical  technics  used  in  the  studies  presented 
by  the  Corporation,  that  there  still  remains  the  probabiUty  that  a  re- 
duction in  price  would  produce  more  increase  in  income  and  less  in- 
crease in  cost  than  the  Corporation  has  assumed.  In  consequence,  a 
reduction  in  price  would  cause  less  increase  in  deficit  than  the  Corpo- 
ration assumes  and  might  even  produce  an  increase  in  profit. 

This  reinterpretation  of  the  results  of  the  analyses  presented  may 
prove  of  interest  to  many  of  the  people  in  the  steel  business  who  may 
have  been  puzzled  "by  the  dilemma  to  which  the  original  analyses  led. 
As  these  analyses  stood,  they  sum  up  in  this  conclusion,  which  was 
stated  on  page  38  of  "Exhibit  No.  1416,"  entitled  "An  Analysis  of 
Steel  Prices,  Volume  and  Costs,"  and  I  quote: 

That  unless  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  the  product  exceeds  1  by  a  substantial 
margin,  the  theory  that  price  reduction  in  and  by  -itself  would  produce  profits 
through  increased  volume  is  utterly  fallacious,  not  only  for  the  United  States 
Steel  Corporation,  but  for  any  business  or  any  industry.  *  *  *  Application 
of  the  theory  of  increased  profits  through  price  reduction  could  thus  only  produce 
loss  to  the  enterprise  which  adopted  it. 


13686  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

If  that  statement  were  turned  the  other  way  around  it  would  equally 
have  proved  that  any  industry  situated  as  the  steel  industry  is  situ- 
ated, would  increase  its  profit  by  increasing  its  price  and  reducing  its 
output,  since  to  increase  the  price  would  bring  an  increase  in  total 
income,  while  the  reduced  volume  would  produce  a  aet  reduction  in 
costs. 

So  that  many  other  industries  in  the  same  position  at  the  same 
time  could  all  make  more  money  by  producing  less  product  and  by 
selling  it  at  a  higher  price.  That  is  the  conclusion  which  the  steel 
analysis  leaves. 

They  don't  carry  it  to  that  point,  but  presumably  the  largest  profit 
would  be  reached  when  1  ton  of  steel  was  produced  by  the  industry 
and  sold  at  a  price- of  a  billion  dollars  a  ton,  since  that  would  involve 
practically  no  cost  except  the  fixed  cost  and  you  would  have  all  profit. 
It  is  obvious  if  all  corporations  attempted  to  follow  this  theory  at  the 
same  time  that  not  only  would  most  workers  be  unemployed,  but 
nobody  would  be  able  to  pay  the  high  prices  for  the  product. 

FAILURE    OF   HIGH    PRICES   TO    PROMOTE    BUSINESS 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  So  the  theory  that  all  businesses  can  make  more 
money  by  all  producing  less  and  all  charging  higher  prices  at  the  same 
time  obviously  cannot  be  true.  It  may  be  comforting  to  those  who 
have  been  troubled  by  this  fundamental  dilemma  to  which  the  results 
lead  that  these  conclusions  rest  upon  a  very  narrow  view  of  the  in- 
dustrial process  and  only  hold  true  on  the  assumption  that  the  steel 
industry  operates  without  effect  upon  the  rest  of  the  economy. 

The  reinterpretation  I  have  just  presented  may  be  summarized 
briefly  in  the  statement  that  the  conclusions  of  the  Steel  Corporation 
have  made  no  allowance  for  the  fact  that  with  changes  in  the  prices  of 
iron  and  steel  products  and  the  volume  of  steel  operations  there  would 
also  be  associated  changes  in  the  prices  of  other  products  and  in  the 
volume  of  operation  of  the  economy  as  a  whole. 

So  when  allowances  are  made  for  that  broader  effect  of  changes  in 
steel  prices,  the  conclusions  reached  may  be  quite  different  from  those 
reached  by  the  Corporation.  In  fact,  they  would  have  to  be  very 
greatly  different  unless  the  further  conclusion  is  to  follow  that  private 
enterprise  organized  in  the  corporate  system  can  only  lead,  if  they 
follow  the  profit  motive,  to  .smaller  and  smaller  output  and  more 
and  more  unemployment,  and  that  the  only  way  that  increased  pro- 
duction and  fuller  employment  can  be  reached  would  be  by  substituting 
some  other  method  of  economic  organization  in  place  of  the  present 
right  of  corporate  managers  of  industry  to  decide  what  prices  to  es- 
tabhsh.  It  is  not  beheved  that  either  the  stcd  companies  or  thif 
committee  would  wish  to  reach  that  further  conclusion. 

Mr.  Walter  White.  Isn't  your  conclusion  in  that  respect  depen- 
dent upon  the  nonexistence  of  competition  to  affect  prices. 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  I  am  taking  the  statements  made  by  the  Steel 
Corporation  for  the  industry  in  their  presentation  as  representing  the 
way  that  the  industry  operates.  They  discuss  in  their  presentation 
the  possibility  of  increasing  prices  or  decreasing  prices  as  if  it  lay 
within  their  power  to  make  the  choice  quite  without  the  effect  of 
competition. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13687 

Mr.  White.  That  is  not  my  recollection  of  the  testimony  that 
Dr.  Yntema  gave.  I  don't  think  you  were  here,  but  that  point  came 
up.  He  was  asked  whether  50  percent  in  reduction  in  production 
and  50  percent  increase  in  price  would  make  more  money  for  the 
Corporation  and  he  said  "yes."  When  asked  why  they  didn't  do  it, 
he  said  competition  in  the  industry,  so  I  feel  that  is  apphcable  to 
industry  as  a  whole  on  that  particular  argument. 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  I  am  sorry,  I  didn't  hear  Dr.  Yntema's  verbal 
discussion.  I  have  read  the  various  documents,  particularly  the 
document  which  compares  the  cost  andlysis  with  the  price  analysis, 
and  as  I  read  that  document,  it  read  in  terms  of  "if  this  price  policy 
were  followed,  such-and-such  results  would  follow;  if  this  price  policy 
were  followed,  such  and  such  results  would  follow,"  and  included  the 
statement  which  I  quoted  to  the  effect  that  it  would  never  pay  any 
industry  like  steel  to  reduce  its  price.  As  I  pointed  out,  the  same' 
data  just  as  readily  lead  to  the  opposite  conclusion  that  it  would 
always  pay  any  industry  like  steel  to  raise  its  price.  I  -haven't  con- 
sidered how  many  other  industries  are  situated  like  steel,  but  have 
pointed  out  that  if  there  were  many,  and  all  of  them  followed  the 
principle  that  they  could  make  the  biggest  profit  by  always  raising 
price,  it  would  be  pretty  hard  on  everybody  else. 

There  is  a  third  range  of  possibiUty  which  lies  rather  outside  the 
scope  of  the  material  considered  in  the  Steel  Corporation's  statement. 

Dr.  Yntema,  I  believe,  had  just  one  passing  reference  to  it;  it  was 
indicated  in  the  third  assumption  that  I  stated  in  the  beginning. 
Throughout  their  analysis  the  Corporation  claimed  thafr  changes  in 
steel  prices  have  Uttle  or  no  effect  on  the  demand  of  the  final  consumer 
for  the  products  finally  made  from  steel.  That  result  foUows,  they 
claim,  since  the  price  of  steel  makes  up  such  a  relatively  small  fraction 
of  the  cost  of  finished  automobiles,  houses,  tractors,  locomotives, 
watches,  and  other  products.  It  is  rather  interesting  to  note  exactly 
that  same  argument,  that  the  price  of  their  product  makes  only  a  very 
small  percent  of  the  finished  product,  is  made  by  lumber  men  in 
explaining  why  reduced  lumber  prices  would  not  increase  the  sale 
of  houses,  by  members  of  building  unions  in  explaining  why  reduced 
per  hour  wage  rates,  for  bricklayers  and  carpenters,  would  not  increase 
the  sale  of  houses,  and  by  farmers  iu  explaining  why  reduced  wheat 
prices  do  not  increase  the  sale  of  bread. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Dr.  Ezekiel,  do  you  mean  to  say  that  we  could  use  this 
same  multiple  correlation  technic  which  Dr.  Yntema  has  exploited  to 
prove  an  inelastic  demand  for  steel  and  establish  by  identical  methods 
an  iuelastic.  demand  for,  let's  say,  a  particular  group  of  craftsmen  of 
union  labor  in  the  steel  industry? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  No;  that  is  not  my  argument  at  this  point.  I  am  not 
referring  to  the  technic  of  the  statistical  analysis  here,  but  rather  to  the 
computation  that  since  steel,  say,  makes  only  one-tenth  of  the  cost  of 
a  finished  automobile,  if  you  reduce  the  price  of  steel  10  percent,  you 
would  reduce  the  automobile  price  only  1  percent,  and  that  doesn't 
make  any  difference. 

'Dr.  Kreps.  Isn't  that  the  identical  argument  of  the  plasterer 
when  he  says,  "Why  shouldn't  I  get  $26  a  day?  It  makes  a  difference 
of  only  a  fraction  of  a  percent  in  the  cost  of  a  house.  There  will  be 
no  stimulation  of  the  demand  for  houses.  People  are  not  going  to 
buUd  any  more  houses  if  I  take  only  $18." 


13088        CONCENTKATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Exactly. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Therefore,  if  labor  argues  that  way,  what  do  we  call 
that  type  of  reasoning?     Is  that  the  lump  of  labor  fallacy,  so-called? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  I  am  not  trymg  to  attach  terms  to  these;  I  am  just 
trying  to  point  out  the  argument  involved. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Isn't  it  true  that  is  called  the  lump  of  labor  fallacy? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Yes;  it  is  in  the  case  of  labor. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Therefore,  when  it  is  argued  that  general  social  policy 
should  be  based  upon  computations  of  this  sort,  actually  you  have  a 
lump  of  business  fallacy  on  advanced  mathematical  stilts. 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Yes;  I  guess  you  can  caU  it  that;  I  realize  that  as 
the  steel  industry  is  now  organized,  and'  as  the  activity  legally  per- 
mitted corporations  of  this  country  is  now  circumscribed,  there  is 
probably  no  wa}"^  by  which  changes  in  steel  prices  can  be  coordinated 
with  changes  in  other  prices,  although  it  might  be  interesting  to  point 
out  in  this  connection  that  as  far  as  I  am  aware,  the  anti-trust  laws 
are  solely  directed  against  combinations  in  restraint  of  trade,  and 
that  so  far  as  I  know,  there  has  never  been  a  case  to  test  whether 
combinations  for  the  expansion  of  trade  would  be  similarly  illegal. 

QUESTION    OF    CONCERTED    ACTION   TO    EXPAND    PROJ)UCTION 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  But  as  bus'ness  corporations  do  operate,  it  is  no  doubt 
true  that  there  is  no  existir  ;  means  by  which  reductions  in  steel  prices 
could  be  brought  about  co  currently  with  reductions  in  cement  prices, 
lumber  prices,  freight  rates,  automobile  prices,  furniture  prices,  houses, 
and  perhaps  even  wage  rates  per  hour,  though  not  necessarily  incomes 
per  year  of  workers  engaged  in  some  of  the  more  highly  paid  trades 
such  as  steam  fitters,  carpentiers,  and  bricklayers.  It  is  perfectly  ob- 
vious that  if  some  means  could  be  found  by  which  concerted  reductions 
could  oe  made  in  the  prices  of  many  products  at  the  same  time,  the 
additions  of  these  savings  all  down  the  line  would  add  up  to  a  very 
much  greater  reduction  in  price  of  the  final  finished  product  than  would 
be  possible  if  only  a  single  industry  made  the  change  in  price.  So  in 
periods  of  great  economic  contraction  such  as  that  which  occurred  in 
1930  to  '32,  or  again  in  late  1937  and  '38,  it  should  be  possible  for 
such  concerted  reductions  jn  price  to  be  accompanied  by  concerted 
expansions  in  output.  The  Steel  Corporation  itself  has  shown  that 
such  an  increase  from  a  low  to  a  high  output  would  greatly  reduce  the 
cost  of  output  per  ton  produced. 

There  have  been  many  discussions  of  the  possibihty  of  concerted 
action  by  industrial  units  which  have  seemed  to  assume  that  the  only 
way  that  such  concerted  action  could  be  brought  about  would  be  for 
the  Government  itself  to  take  over  the  ownership  of  the  industries, 
either  through  pubHc  ownership,  to  use  the  American  term,  or  social- 
ism, to  use  other  terms,  or  else  to  assume  that  the  only  way  that  can 
be  brought  about  would  be  for  the  Government  to  take*  over  complete 
control  of  the  production  policy  of  a  corporation  through  some  sucb 
form  as  fascism.  The  argument  made  on  this  point  has  always 
seemed  to  lead  to  that  conclusion — that  either  you  would  have 
socialism  or  fascism,  either  complete  ownership  or  complete  govern- 
ment regimentation  in  order  to  bring  about  any  such  considered  action 
by  industry.  But  it  seems  to  me  that  there  are  other  possible  technics 
by  which  a  democratic  goveniment  can  find  ways  to  cooperate  with 
industrial  producers  in  assisting  them  to  develop  concerted  programs 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER       13689 

of  production  and  price  change  which  would  not  involve  either  of 
those  extreme  forms  of  economic  organization.  We  do  know  that  in 
agriculture  the  farms  of  this  country  are  still  o-wTied  by  individual 
farmers,  and  we  know  that  the.  programs  of  faTm  production  are 
workeci  out  democratically  with  ue  participation  and  approval  of 
individual  farmers,  with  a  very  great  deal  of  planning  from  the 
bottom  up  through  township  committees,  (*ounty  committees.  State 
committees,  and  regional  committees  •  so  that  the  farm  programs 
that  are  in  effect  are  not  programs  imposed  from  Washington,  but  are 
programs  worked  out  from  grass  roots  up,  representing  the  decision 
of  farmers  as  to  what  they  feel  needs  to  be  done  after  they  go  over  the 
fact. 

Yet  at  the  same  time  through  these  programs  the  producers  pf  the 
major  export  crops  working  through  the  A.  A.  A.  and  associated 
programs  have  found  a  means  of  taking  concerted  action  with  respect 
to  the  acreage  and  price  of  their  major  crops  without  involving  either 
socialism  or  fascism.  So  the  fact  that  it  hag  been  possible  to  work  out 
democratic  procedures  and  carry  through  concerted  action  in  the  field 
of  agriculture  may  suggest  that  parallel  democratic  procedures  could 
be  -developed  in  the  field  of  industry,  .and  that  through  those  demo- 
cratic procedures,  production  might  jbe  increased,  prices  might  be 
reduced,  and  employment  raised  on  a  larger  scale  than  individual 
industries  have  been  able  to  estabhsh  and  maintain  during  recent 
years. 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  Pardon  me,  but  have  I  misunderstood  what  has 
happened  imder  A.  A.-  A?  Was  the  procedure  one  whpch  reduced 
prices  and  increased  prodiiction,  or  was  it  merely  the  fact  that  dis- 
cussions had  taken  place  democratically,  in  which  you  are  suggesting 
the  parallel? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  No;  it  is  obvious  that  A.  A.  A.  has  not  been  aimed 
at  the  further  expansion  of  agricultural  production  in  the  face  of  the 
very  low  market  for  farm  products  which  have  resulted  from  a  low 
industrial  production.  I  am  bringing  the  A.  A.  A.  experience  into 
evidence  merely  to  show  that  i.t  is  possible  to  bring  producers  together 
on  concerted  programs  of  action,  and  that  those  concerted  programs  of 
action  can  be  devised  through  democratic  procedures. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Dr.  Ezekiel,  do  you  think  that  method  of  procedure 
is  applicable  and  practical  in  the  case  of  an  industry  where  you  have 
9  or  10  concerns  controlling  80  percent  of  the  output? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Yes.  I  beheve  it  would  be  infinitely  easier  to  sit 
down  around  a  table  with  8  or  10  men  and  work  out  what  each  indus- 
try should  do  than  to  go  out  into  the  field  to  develop  an  agricultural 
program  by  discussing  it  with  two  or  three  million  cotton  producers 
or  one  milhon  wheat  producers,  and  get  those  several  million  producers 
to  take  concerted  action. 

Mr.  Wooden.  It  would  be  decidedly  easier  to  get  concerted  action? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Yes.  It  should  be  easier  in  industry.  If  you  did  get 
concerted  action  among  each  of  the  great  industries,  each  of  them 
expanding  its  production  in  the  proper  proportion,  then  you  would 
have  larger  markets  and  you  would  have  a  material  reduction  in  the 
final  price  which  would  make  it  possible  to  move  the  products  into 
consumption. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Was  not  cooperation  among  the  farmers  for  the  pur- 
poses of  decreasing  production  and  increasing  price? 


13690  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Yes,  sir;  that  is  what  Mr.  Hinrichs  has  just  pointed 
out. 

Mr.  Wooden.  You  would  favor  that  in  the  case  of  all  industries? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  No.  As  matters  now  stand,  if  a  single  industry  takes 
concerted  action  to  decide  what  it  should  do,  whether  that  single 
industry  be  agriculture  or  whether  it  be  the  petroleum  industry  or  the 
anthracite  coal  industry  or  the  bituminous  coal  industry,  operating 
as  a  single  industry,  the  thing  it  is  most  likely  to  do  is  to  say,  "The 
market  for  our  product  is  only  so  much;  national  activity  is  so  much, 
and  this  limits  the  market  for  our  product.  Therefore,  we  as  a  single 
industry,  must  be  careful  not  to  produce  too  much  for  our  market." 
That,  of  course,  is  what  the  steel  industry  has  done  in  the  past,  when 
it  has  so  greatly  cut  down  its  production. 

What  I  am  proposing,  however,  is  that  a  iiumber  of  the  great 
industries,  each  at  the  same  time,  expand  their  production  so  that 
their  iotsd  market  will  not  be  determined  by  the  present  relatively 
low  production  and  national  income  of  the  whole  country,  but  will 
be  determined  by  the  much  larger  production  and  national  income 
which  they  are  all  proceeding  to  create.  One  industry  by  itself 
cannot  expand  national  production  as  effectively  as  can  many  indus- 
tries working  together.  Only  concerted  action  taken  among  many 
great  industries  at  the  same  time  can,  by  that  action,  make  a  bigger 
market  for  the  product. 

Mr.  Hinrichs.  Pardon  me,  but  you  said  one  industry  cannot 
expand  national  production,  and  a  little  earlier  we  had  one  industry 
that  was  exj)anding  national  production.  You  mean  that  one 
industry,  acting  by  itself,  cannot  expand  national  activity  to  a 
sufficiently  large  extent  to  benefit  or  to  be  certain  of  benefiting 
financially  from  that  expansion  in  national  activity?  You  don't 
mean  to  go  back  on  your  earlier  statement  that  that  3  percent  expan- 
sion on  a  10  percent  reduction  price  is  going  to  have  in  and  of.  itself 
some  beneficial  effect  on  the  rest  of  the  economy,  though  it  might 
be  bad  for  the  stockholders  of  the  Steel  Corporation? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Yes.  My  statement  should  be  that  one  industry 
by  itself  cannot  produce  anything  like  as  much  effect  on  national 
income  as  can  concerted  action  by  many  industries.  You  are  quite 
correct: 

And  now,  the  testimony  that  the  Steel  Corporation  has  put  in, 
that  it  would  never  pay  them  to  reduce  prices,  suggests  that  private 
corporations,  if  they  continue  to  operate  in  the  next  few  years  with  the 
same  philosophy  as  that  which  has  controlled  their  operations  in 
recent  years,  will  never  fmd  ways  to  solve  the  large  and  continuing 
unemployment.  And  yet,  if  private  enterprise  is  to  survive,  business 
must  find  a  way  under  private  enterprise  to  solve  the  problem  of 
unemployment  and  to  provide  a  continuing  rise  in  the  standard  of 
living — more  goods  to  consume  for  each  day's  work. 

Now,  in  concluding  this  statement,  I  would  like  to  indicate  that  I  am 
quite  aware  of  the  fact  that  no  way  has  yet  been  developed  and  put 
into  action  by  which  the  officers  of  the  Steel  Corporation  or  any  of 
the  great  corporations  similarly  situated  could  take  such  concerted 
action  to  reduce  prices  and  increase  production  in  many  industries 
concurrently  as  that  which  has  just  been  suggested  above,  and  I 
would  also  like  to  indicate  that  the  problem  is  a  much  larger  one 
than  the  problem  of  prices  and  production  alone,  because  expansion 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13691 

in  production  and  in  consumption  and  employment  can  be  continued 
and  maintained  only  if  the  buying  power  that  is  made  available  to  the 
workers  of  the  country  is  increased  rapidly  enough  so  that  the  con- 
sumer demand  for  the  various  products  produced  rises  in  proper 
proportion  to  what  is  being  produced.  In  other  words,  if  you  increase 
production  and  don't  give  your  consumers,  the  people  of  the  country, 
enough  income  to  buy  the  output,  you  cannot  maintain  increased 
output. 

On  the  other  hand,  if  you  do  increase  buying  power  in  proportion 
to  the  increased  output,  then  that  will  call  into  action  still  further 
increases  in  production  and  further  expansions  in  plant  capacity. 

The  problem  of  devising  a  program  of  concerted  industrial  expansion 
so  as  to  secure  a  proper  proportioning  of  the  changes  in  prices,  wages, 
production,  employment,  investment,  and  expansion  in  plant  and 
equipment,  is  much  more  intricate  and  extensive  than  can  appro- 
priately be  discussed  at  this  point.  However,  as  I  understand  the 
job  which  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  is  attacking, 
it  is  to  suggest  ways  by  which  the  productive  facilities  of  this  country 
can  be  used  to  the  fullest  extent  so  as  to  secure  a  steadily  rising 
standard' of  Hving  and  so  as  to  insure  that  the  steady  increase  in 
technological  efficiency  and  in  industrial  arts  and  sciences  shall  produce 
hereafter  a  steadily  rising  level  of  consumption  for  all  our  citizens, 
instead  of  producing,  as  they  have  so  often  up  to  this  time,  a  steadily 
increasing  proportion  of  our  citizens  who  are  barred  from  normal 
participation  in  society. 

While  the  Steel  Corporation  alone  is  not  in  a  position  to  bring  about 
such  modifications  in  laws  and  methods  of  business  organization  as 
might  lead  toward  this  result,  the  T.  N.  E.  C.  is  in  a  position  to 
consider  such  changes. .  It  is  for  that  reason  that  I  have  presented  this 
final  discussion  of  ways  in  which  concerted  price  reductions  might 
bring  about  higher  profits  and  higher  employment  even  if  individual 
corporations  such  as  the  Steel  Corporation,  are  not  now  in  a  position 
to  undertake  such  concerted  operations. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  Are  there  any  questions? 

Mr.  HiNEicHS.  I  have  two  further  questions.  You  speak  of 
concerted  action  to  achieve  price  reductions.  I  suppose  you  are  dis- 
tinguishing there  between  concerted  action  and  simultaneous  action. 
It  is  conceivable  that  under  conditions  of  competition  between  small 
producing  units,  it  would  not  require  willful  action  of  any  significant 
extent  to  reduce  prices.  Industrial  producers  would  find  themselves 
in  much  the  same  position  that  farmers  find  themselves  in.  Prices 
of  farm  products,  as  I  understand  it,  have  gone  down  more  pr  less 
simultaneously,  not  because  of  any  concerned  action  by  farm  pro- 
ducers, but  because  of  the  effect  of  competition  against  large  producing 
capacity  in  periods  when  national  income  goes  down.  Is  that  not 
correct? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Yes;  that  is  quite  correct;  but  if  all  of  our  industries 
were  organized  on  as  competitive  a  basis  as  most  farm  production  is 
organized,  or  was  organized  prior  to  A.,  A.  A.,  and  for  that  matter,  as 
competitive  as  most  cotton  textile  proaucers  are  organized  and  many 
dress  goods  producers,  then  when  people  are  unemployed,  when 
demand  is  low,  competition  would  force  prices  to  fall  together,  and 
you  would  get  as  a  result  of  competition,  an  expansion  in  employment 
and  expansion  m  production.     But  as  our  economy  is  organized  today, 

124491 — 41— pt.  26 8 


13692        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

not  only  steel  but  many  other  great  industries,  seem  to  be  so  organized 
that  prices  do  not  fall  when  demand  goes  down,  or  at  least,  prices  do 
not  fall  anything  like  as  rapidly  as  they  do  in  other  industries.  In- 
stead, output  is  reduced  as  demand  falls. 

Mr.  HiNRicHS.  That  is,  your  prices  under  competitive  conditions, 
willy-nilly  would  normally  fall  to  something  approximating  the  vari- 
able costs  of  the  marginal  producer;  that  is,  if  we  were  to  assume 
that  these  variable  costs  oi  $55  a  ton  represented  marginal  costs, 
irrespective  of  whether  or  not  it  is  a  good  thing  for  the  owners  of  a 
particular  business,  you  would  expect  large  amounts  of  unused 
capacity  to  drive  prices  down  to  something  approximately  close  to 
that  $55  level.     Is  that  correct? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Yes;  we  had  it  in  agriculture.  Prices  fell  far  below 
the  level  that  covered  the  computed  cost  of  all  the  costs  involved  in 
the  business,  but  farmers  produced  and  sold  in  spite  of  that  because 
there  wasn't  anything  else  they  could  do  under  competition. 

Mr.  HiNRiCHS.  Now,  the  corollary  of  what  you  have  been  saying 
with  reference  to  concerted  action  to  reduce  prices  and  expand  pro- 
duction, if  I  understand  you  correctly,  is  that  any  concerted  action 
to  maintain  prices,  while  it  may  be  beneficial  to  the  particular  industry 
involved,  is  by  just  that  extent  deleterious  to  all  of  the  rest  of  the 
economy.  All  the  other  units  that  are  also  dependent  upon  the  total 
volume  of  national  income  and  industrial  activity  suffer  from  the 
curtailment  that  is  involved  in  the  maintenance  of  high  prices.  Is 
that  correct? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Yes;  that  is  correct  and  is  borne  out  by  the  experience 
of  the  last  depression.  During  the  last  depression,  beginning  in  1929, 
each  of  these  industries  that  have  only  limited  competition  sought  to 
restrict  their  output  so  as  to. maintain  their  price,  but  each  of  them 
suffered  from  the  fact  that  many  other  industries  were  doing  the  same 
thing.  As  a  result,  demand  as  a  whole  was  collapsing,  and  even  with 
restricted  output,  these  industries  still  had  difficulty  maintaining 
price. 

I  would  like  to  go  back  to  a  couple  of  the  other  points  you  made 
earlier,  just  to  clear  up  the  issues  raised.  You  were  quite  correct 
that  I  used  the  term  "concerted  action"  as  opposed  to  "simultaneous 
action."  Many  of  these  industries  do  have  such  a  concentration  of 
corporate  control,  have  production  in  the  hands  of  such  a  small 
number  of  producers,  tli^t  anything  like  free  competition  just  cannot 
take  place.  The  only  way  they  can  take  action  of  the  sort  I  have 
described  is  if  they  definitely  plan  it,  if  they  definitely  get  together 
and  arrange,  both  in  each  controlled  industry  and  between  the  different 
industries,  to  move  together  on  a  program  to  reduce  price  and  increase 
production. 

May  I  make  one  more  point  on  this  question  that  Dr.  Hinrichs 
raised?  You  asked  if  the  fall  in  price  in  competitive  industries  would 
not  tend  to  produce  that  result — increased  production — automatically. 
In  that  connection  it  is  interesting  to  contrast  what  happened  to  the 
steel  industry  itself  after  the  very  high  prices  of  the  immediate  post- 
war period,  in  1919  and  1920,  and  after  the  prices  of  1929. 

After  the  war-inflation  boom,  when  demand  fell  off  in  1921  and  1922, 
there  was  apparently  much  more  competition  in  steel  then  than  there 
is  now,  because  steel  prices  did  come  down  very,  very  rapidly.  Other 
prices  came  down  even  more  rapidly.     The  decline  in  nominal  steel 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13693 

prices  from  the  high  in  1919  to  the  low  in  1921  was  as  great  as  in  all 
commodities,  but  the  decline  in  actual  mill  net  yield  was  not  so  great, 
according  to  the  data  filed  by  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation. 

The  depression  of  1921-22  was  over  very  promptly,  at  least  com- 
pared to  this  past  depression.  After  the  war  boom,  the  post-war 
depression  involved  a  rapid  d^op  in  price  of  almost  all  industrial 
products,  and  brought  about  a  prompt  increase  in  production  and 
increase  in  employment,  so  that  by  1923,  new  high  levels  were  being 
made  in  production.  But  during  the  depression  of  1929,  industrial 
prices  did  not  fall  as  greatly,  and  instead  of  having  a  short  depression, 
even  though  a  hard  one,  with  a  prompt  recovery,  the  recovery  didn't 
come  and  didn't  come,  and  stUl  has  not  come  in  full  measure. 

Mr.  Wooden.  If,  as  you  say,  it  is  impractical  to  expect. competition 
in  an  indu'^^try  such  as  steel,  and  if  no  one  of  the  9  or  10  producers  who 
control  collectively  some  80  percent  of  the  output  wiU  reduce  prices  as  a 
matter  of  competition,  what  reason  is  there  to  expect  that  they  will  do 
it  if  they  are  permitted  to  take  concerted  action? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Well,  I  haven't  suggested  that  merely  by  permitting 
them  to  take  concerted  action,  it  would  necessarily  result  in  their 
doing  so. '  In  fact,  I  was  discussing  not  merely  concerted  action  in  the 
steel  industry,  but  concerted  action  in  a  number  of  great  industries  at 
the  same  time,  in  the  steel  industry  and  the  automobile  industry  and 
the  cement  industry  and  the  glass  industry  and  in  a  number  of  other 
industries. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Under  some  form  of  Government  control,  you  mean? 

Dr.  EzEKiEt.  Under  some  form  of  Government  participation,  suffi- 
ciently to  insure  that  the  action  taken  by  industry  would  be-  in  the 
general  welfare.  I  have  discussed  elsewhere  various  forms  of  organi- 
zation that  might  be  used  to  bring  about  that  result. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Dr.  Ezeldel,  are  you  familiar  with  the  proposals  of 
Prof.  O.  M.  W.  Sprague  of  Harvard  University  in  this  regard? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  I  have  a  general  acquaintance  with  them.  I  am  not 
sure  that  I  can  expound  them  in  full. 

Dr.  Kreps.  As  you  imderstand  his  proposals,  does  he  recommend 
that  in  the  building  field  there  be  some  such,  as  you  have  said,  con- 
certed action  or  simultaneous  action,  in  order  to  reduce  costs  of 
housing? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Yes;  I  believe  that  he  pointed  out  that  if  you  really 
wanted  to  get  housing  costs  down,  you  had  to  get  reductions  aU  along 
the  line,  and  that  if  you  get  reductions  by  all  the  persons  who  partici- 
pated in  the  housing,  you  could  expect  to  get  such  an  increase  in 
houses  sold  as  to  bring  about  a  benefit  for  all  involved. 

Dr.  Keeps.  And  as  I  understand  your  point  it  is  the  pertinent 
consideration,  if  we  want  to  increase  the  volume  of  housing.  If  we 
took  each  particular  commodity,  we  could  show  that  in  each  particular 
case  that  a  reduction  in  price  would  have  a  negligible  effect  on  the 
total  volume  of  housing;  isn't  that  correct? 

Dr.  Ezekiel.  Yes;  I  believe  that  is  correct  for  housing. 

Dr.  Keeps.  We  could  prove  it  for  each  individual,  particular  case, 
and  yet  when  we  added  it  up,  our  results,  instead  of  being  a  sum  total 
of  the  individual  effects,  would  be  according  to  Dr.  Sprague  and  accord- 
ing to  your  analysis,  diametrically  opposite.  The  social  effect,  in 
other  words,  is.  entirely  different  from  the  sum  total  of  individual 
effects.     The  results  of  particular  studies,  of  each  of  the  materials  that 


13694       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

goes  into  a  house  and  each  of  the  skilled  groups  of  ^ftbor,  do  not  give 
us  a  guide  for  public  policy  with  respect  to  housing;  is  that  correct? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Well 

Dr.  Kreps  (interposing).  It  is  the  total  picture  that  you  regard  as 
important? 

Dr.  EzEKiEL.  Yes;  studying  any  one  pait  of  it  does  not  necessarily 
tell  what  the  possibilities  are  if  the  problem  is  dealt  with  as  a  whole. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  Are  there  any  other  questions? 
Have  you  any  other  questions  you  would  like  to  ask,  Dr.  KJreps? 

Dr.  Keeps.  No,  you  may  dismiss  the  witness. 

Acting  Chau-man  O'Connell.  Thank  you  very  much,  Doctor.  I 
think  that  is  all. 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  would  now  like  to  sunamoit  Mr.  Martin  Taitel  to  the 
stand. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  Have  you  been  sworn  yet? 

Mr.  Taitel.  No;  I  have  not. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  Do  you  solemnly  swear  that  the 
testimony  which  you  are  about  to  give  in  this  proceeding  shall  be 
the  truth,  the  whole  truth  and  nothing  but  the  truth,  so  help  you  God? 

Mr.  Taitel.  I  do. 

TESTIMONY  OF  MARTIN  TAITEL,  SENIOR  CONSULTING  ECONO- 
MIST, WORK  PROJECTS  ADMINISTRATION,  WASHINGTON,  D.  C. 

Dr.  Kreps.  For  the  purpose  of  the  record,  Mr.  Taitel,  will  you 
state  your  full  name  and  address? 

Mr.  Taitel.  Martin  Taitel. 

Dr.  Kreps.  And  your  address? 

Mr. 'Taitel.  Chevy  Chase,  Md. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  have  been  formerly  with  the  N.  R.  A.  as  economic 
adviser  on  codes  and  statistician? 

Mr.  Taitel.  Yes. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Where  did  you  receive  the  bulk  of  your  training  in 
statistics? 

Mr.  Taitel.  Under  Professor  Yntema  at  the  University  of  Chicago. 
I  should  like  to  say  that  I  am  very  proud  to  have  received  my  training 
from  Professor  Yntema;  I  hope  he  will  be  as  proud  of  the  product  of 
his  training. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  have  prepared  a  statement  for  us.  Is  it  the  one 
to  which  we  heard  something  of  a  rebuttal  this  morning? 

Mr.  Taitel.  I  should  say  a  rebuttal  in  part. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  may  proceed. 

Mr»  Taitel.  The  steel  industry  has  rather  generally  been  regarded 
as  an  industry  with  high  "fixed"  costs,  that  is,  one  o£  these  industries 
in  which  unit  costs  of  production  decline  as  output  increases. 

So  far  as  prices  in  such  an  industry  are  based  upon  costs,  the 
pricing  policy  would  tend  to  be  one  that  provides  for  dechning  prices 
as  the  volume  of  output  increases.  Prices  in  the  steel  industry, 
however,  have  not  followed  this  pattern.  They  have  tended  to 
remain  relatively  fixed.  The  typical  practice  has  been  to  increase 
prices  with  increased  volume  rather  than  to  decrease  prices  as  sales 
expand.  Such  price  behavior  is  much  more  consistent  with  a  situation 
m  which  increasmg  output  is  associated  with  constant  or  rising  costs. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13695 

UNITED  STATES   STEEL  CORPORATION  ANALYSIS   OF   COSTS  IN   RELATION 
TO  PRICE  DECISION-MAKING 

Mr.  Taitel.  The  statistical  analysis  of  costs  presented  to  this 
committee  by  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  is  designed  to 
dciend  the  pricing  system  practiced  by  the  Steel  Corporation.  It  is 
designed  to  show  that  the  price  policy  actually  pursued  by  the  corpora- 
tion has  been  in  considerable^  measure  dictated  by  its  costs.  The 
illusion  is  created  in  the  analysis  prepared  by  the  Corporation  that  the 
great  bulk  of  the  Corporation's  costs  vary  directly  with  the  number 
of  tons  of  steel  it  produces.  This  illusion  has  been  attained  by  dis- 
solving the  distinction  between  fixed  and  variable  costs.  All  costs, 
except  bond  interest  and  pensions,  are  treated  as  if  they  were  made 
up  of  fixed  and  variable  elements  which  can  be  segregated  by  means 
of  highly  refined  statistical  techniques,  but  cannot  be  segregated  on 
tRe  basis  of  direct  observation.  The  net  result  of  such  manipulation 
is  the  one  obtained  by  the  Corporation,  namely,  costs  are  in  the 
main  shown  to  be  "variable'-'  costs.  But,  unless  one  accepts  the  highly 
sophistical  theories  upon  which  the  numerical  calculations  are  based, 
one  cannot  accept  the  Corporation's  analysis  as  a  true  reflection  of  the 
cost  situation  in  the  steel  industry  as  a  basis  for  price  policy. 

Any  cost  accountant  or  statistician  working  with  cost  figures  can 
attain  a  variety  of  cost-volume  relations  by  varying  the  methods  of 
computing  or  stating  costs.  This  is  strikingly  illustrated  by  the 
sharply  contrasting  results  obtained  by  the  "Iron  Age"  and  the  United 
States  Steel  Corporation.  Mr.  T.  W.  Lippert,  metallurgical  editor 
of  "Iron  Age",  presents,  in  this  year's  January  4  issue  of  that  journal, 
a  production-profit  curve  based  upon  his  examination  of  "production- 
profit  data  of  two  large  steel  companies — both  integrated  producers 
and  both  makers  of  practically  all  types  of  steel,  from  fine  wire  to 
structural  shapes  and  including  low  alloy  steels."  The  results  pre- 
sented differ  from  the  comparable  results  of  the  Corporation's  analysis. 

I  should  like,  Mr.  Chairman,  at  this  point,  to  offer  for  the  record 
a  chart  entitled,  "Contrast  in  Production-Profit  Computations." 

Dr.  Kreps.  Will  you  display  the  chart,  please? 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  It  may  be  admitted. 

(The  chart  referred  to  was  marked  "Exhibit  No.  2184"  and  is 
included  in  the  appendix  on  p.  14120.) 

Mr.  Taitel.  The  Corporation's  analysis  purports  to  show  that 
profits  vary  directly  with  output;  namely,  the  addition  to  profit  is 
the  same  for  each  additional  ton  of  steel  sold. 

Mr.  Lippert's  analysis,  on  the  pther  hand,  purports  to  show  that 
the  relation  between  profits  and  production  is  decidedly  not  of  this 
direct  character  but  that  changes  in  output  produce  profits  of  varying 
magnitudes,  depending  upon  the  rate  of  capacity  at  which  plants  are 
operated.  According  to  his  analysis,  the  rate  of  profit  per  additional 
ton  of  output  increases  rapidly  between  the  break-even  point — 
roughly  45  percent  of  capacity — and  about  80  percent  of  capacity. 
Above  the  80-percent  level  there  is  only  a  very  small  profit  per 
additional  ton  of  output  until  a  rate  of  capacity  somewhere  around 
the  90-percent  level  is  reached,  after  which  a  loss  is  associated  with 
each  additional  ton  to  full  capacity.  Furthermore,  according  to  Mr. 
Lippert's  study,   below  the  break-even  point  losses  increase  very 


13696       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

slowly  as  operations  are  reduced  to  about  20  percent  of  capacity  and 
tbea  increase  sharply  as  the  operating  rate  approaches  zero. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Mr.  Taitel,  will  you  turn  to  the  chart  and  indicate  the 
significance  of  what  you  haVe  just  testified? 

Mr.  Taitel.  This  is  Mr.  Lippert's  curve  and  he  shows  that  from 
the  break-even  point 

Dr.  Kreps  (interposing).  Just  a  second.  That  is  Mr.  Lippert's 
curve  reproduced  from  the  January  4  issue  of  "Iron  Age"  of  this 


Mr.  Taitel.  Yes. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Do  you  know  who  Mr.  Lippert  is? 

Mr.  Taitel.  He  is  the  metallurgical  editor  of  "Iron  Age." 

Profits  from  the  break-even  point — these  are  total  profits — increase 
much  more  sharply  than  output.  The  increase  in  slope  of  this  curve 
as  it  goes  above  the  break-even  point  indicates  that  the  additional 
profit  per  ton  increases  with  an  increase  in  the  percent  of  capacity 
operatmg.. 

Dr.  Kreps.  How  do6s  that  contrast  with  the  lower  chart,  which  is 
based,  I  take  it,  upon  the  materials  that  have  been  adduced  by  the 
Steel  Corporation? 

Mr.  Taitel.  The  lower  chart  represents  a  situation  in  which  the 
profit  per  additional  ton  is  constant.  ,  As  I  have  plotted  it  here, 
I  believe  for  each  additional  ton,  the  addition  to  profit  is  about  $18. 

Under  Mr.  Lippert's  computations,  losses  do  not  increase  very  rap- 
idly as  operations  decline  below  the  break-even  point. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Of  what  significanae  is  that  fact? 

Mr.  Taitel.  According  to  Mr.  Lippert's  computations,  steel  plants 
are  able  to  operate  between  20  and  45  percent  of  capacity  without 
much  change  in  the  total  loss;  within  that  range  of  output  there  is 
very  little  change  in  the  loss,  assuming,  of  course,  no  change  in  prices. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  mean  if  the  top  curve  is  true  to  fact,  I  take*  it. 
Is  that  right? 

Mr.  Taitel.  Yes.  I  should  perhaps  note  that  in  both  cases  the 
price  structure  is  assumed  to  be  the  same,  so  that  receipts  would  in- 
crease directly  with  output. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Supposing  you  had  a  10-percent  reduction  in  price, 
does  it  make  any  difference  whether  the  condition  of  the  industry  is 
that  as  represented  in  the  top  chart  as  compared  with  that  in  the 
bottom  chart? 

Mr.  Taitel.  It  makes  a  good  deal  of  difference.  Speaking  in  ap- 
proximate general  terms,  a  10-percent  reduction  in  price  would  bear 
less  heavily  on  profits  assuming  Mr.  Lippert's  curve  is  correct  when 
operations  are  above  the  break-even  point  but  below  about  80  percent 
of  capacity.  The  reverse  is  true  below  the  break-even  point  but  above 
about  20  percent  of  capacity.^ 

Dr.  Kreps.  If  you  were  to  take  those  rather  startling  loss  figures 
of  Dr.  Yntema — those*  estimated  loss  figures  guessed  at  but  precisely 
stated  in  dollar  figures,  thus  giving  them  a  specious  and  spurious 
plausibility  and  reminding  one  of  the  cynic's  definition  of  statistics 
as  the  science  that  states  an  uncertainty  with  precision — how  would 

'  In  precise  terms,  the  adverse  effect  upon  profits  of  a  price  reduction  when  output  is  at  a  given  level  is 
greater  for  the  production-profit  curve  with  tne  lesser  slope  between  that  output  level  and  the  new  level  of 
©utput.  Since,  however,  the  scales  for  the  two  curves  are  not  the  same— Mr.  Lippert  providing  no  indica- 
tions of  absolute  amounts  of  profits  oriosses— it  is  not  possible  to  stat«  exactly  the  ranges  of  output  for  which 
lb*  Adverse  effect  is  greater  or  less  for  one  curve  than  for  the  other. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13697 

those  estimated  losses  be  changed  if  the  cost  curve  in  the  industry 
corresponds  to  the  pattern  of  profits  shown  in  the  upper  part  of  your 
chart  ("Exhibit  No.  2184")  as  contrasted  with  that  shown  in  the  lower 
portion  of  your  chart? 

Mr.  Taitel.  I  am  not  sure  that  I  understand  the  question. 
Dr.  Keeps.  I  will  repeat  the  question  in  a  different  form.     Would 
the  estimated  loss  from  a  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel  be  less  or 
greater  if  the  condition  that  Mr.  Lippert  describes  is  true,  than  it  was 
represented  to  be  on  the  charts  that  Mr.  Yn tenia  showed? 

Mr.  Taitel.  The  adverse  effect  upon  profits  resulting  from  reduc- 
tions in  price  would  be  less  in  the  case  of  Mr.  Lippert's  curve  when 
operations  are  approximately  between  the  break-even  point  and  80 
percent. 

Mr.  Walter  White.  Do  you  know  what  statistics  and  figures  Mr. 
Lippert  had  available  from  which  he  derived  his  curve? 

Mr.  Taitel.  He  says  he  used  production  and  profit  data  for  two 
large  steel  companies.  I  have  not  seen  the  detailed  figures.  I  have 
simply  reproduced  the  chart  as  it  appears  in  "Iron  Age." 

Mr.  Walter  White.  Does  it  show  that  a  decline  in  profits  occurs 
after  a  certain  volume  has  been  passed? 

Mr.  Taitel.  That  is  correct.  Beyond  about  90  percent,  total 
profits  decline,  that  is,  for  each  additional  ton  to  expand  from  about 
90  to  100  percent  there  is  a  loss. 

Mr.  Walter  White.  Is  that  because  it  is  in  an  ineflScient  plant, 
do  you  know? 

Mr.  Taitel.  He  states  that  it  is  due  to  general  inefficiencies — trying 
to  meet  particular  orders  of  particular  customers  at  particular  times, 
bringing  in  of  obsolete  capacity,  and  so  on. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Is  it  to  be  understood  that  the  United  States  Steel 
Corporation  is  not  one  of  the  two  that  are  included  in  Mr.  Lippert's 
study? 

Mr.  Taitel.  There  is  no  statement  to  that  effect  in  Mr.  Lippert's 
article.  He  does  not  state  the  names  of  the  two  companies.  I  think, 
though,  that  this  chart  expresses  more  eloquently  than  any  words  at 
my  command  the  different  results  which  can  be  obtained  from  studies 
of  cost  records  in  the  steel  industry. 

My  analysis  of  the  Corporation's  cost  analysis  is  directed  toward 
this  point:  The  arbitrary  nature  of  the  allocation  of  costs  as  between 
years  or  over  portions  of  the  output  makes  it  impossible  for  particular 
cost-volume  computations  such  as  the  Corporation  has  presented  to  be 
the  all-important  basis  of  decisions  as  to  prices.  The  conclusion  is  not 
that  the  Corporation  does  not  have  to  reckon  with  its  money  costs. 
Rather,  the  conglusion  is  that  the  kind  of  cost-volume  relation  which 
the  Corporation  derives  is  not  the  one  relevant  to  price  decision-making 
under  actual  operating  circumstances. 

To  establish  my  main  conclusion,  it  is  necessary  to  establish  two 
others.  First,  that  the  Corporation  in  particular,  and  almost  anj 
business  firm  in  general,  has  a  choice  as  to  when  and  in  what  amount  it 
will  charge  a  considerable  number  of  items  of  expenditure  to  costs. 
And,  second,  that  the  cost-volume  relation  obtained  by  the  Corpora- 
tion's analysts  is  in  large  part  the  consequence  of  the  particular  times 
at  which  it  has  chosen  to  charge  certain  expenditures  to  costs,  and  of 
the  particular  accounting  procedures  by  which  it  has  chosen  to  be 
governed  in  aUocaling  costs. 


13698       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

I  want  to  make  very  clear  the  fact  that  I  am  questioning  neither  the 
validity  nor  the  usefulness  of  the  accounting  procedures  or  records  of 
the  Corporation,  nor  the  statistical  methods  or  procedures  used  by  the 
Corporation's  analysts  when  'they  are  directed  toward  purposes  other 
than  the  one  now  under  discussion.  In  fact,  I,  as  one  who  pretends  to 
be  qualified,  want  to  pay  tribute  publicly  to -the  skillful  and  ingenious 
use  which  has  been  made  of  highly  refined  and  advanced  statistical 
techniques.  I  must,  however,  point  out  that  even  the  most  ingenious 
and  advanced  methods  of  accounting  and  statistical  analysis  may  not 
provide  the  correct  answer  to  the  particular  issue  to  which  they  are 
addressed. 

The  essential  requirement  of  a  costing  system  is  that  it  shall  be  use- 
ful in  terms  of  particular  purposes.  Thus,  in  a  book  written  by  three 
eminent  authorities — Professors  Sanders,  Hatfield  and  Moore — 
published  by  the  American  Institute  of  Accountants  in  1938,  and 
sponsored  by  the  Haskins  and  Sells  Foundation,  there  appears  the 
following  statement: 

Since  the  income  statement  is  prepared  for  the  information  of  owners,  managers, 
creditors,  and  taxing  authorities,  and  for  regulatory  and  other  purposes,  those 
accounting  practices  are  best  which  serve  these  purposes  in  the  most  reliable  and 
helpful  manner. 

It  sometimes  becomes  necessary  to  prepare  separate  statements  to  serve  the 
several  purposes. 

An  eminent  economist — Prof.  J.  M.  Clark — in  his  classic  study, 
"The  Economics  of  Overhead  Costs",  published  in  1923,  points  out — 

*  *  *  the  cost-accounting  conceptions  of  cost  do  not  agree  with  cost  as  used 
by  the  general  accountant,  and  they  disagree  because  they  are  wanted  for  different 
purposes. 

Typi(Sally — and  I  believe  this  is  true  of  the  Corporation — the  costing 
system  is  designed  to  be  useful  for  operating,  tax  or  public-statement 
purposes.  That  such  a  system  should,  without  any  recasting-  of 
accounts,  provide  data  showing  the  "actual"  or  "true"  division  be- 
tween fixed  and  variable  costs  or  the  "actual"  or  "true"  shape  of  the 
marginal  cost  curve  is  not  to  be  expected.  Consequently,  since 
costs  as  entered  on  the  books  are  for  general  purposes,  a  cost  analysis 
based  upon  book  costing  contains  no  inherent  validity. 

Allocation  of  costs  as  between  years  or  as  between  segments  of  out- 
put is  and  must  be  in  part  arbitrary  no  matter  what  accounting  prin- 
ciples and  practices  are  followed.  Many  items  of  cost  have  no  observ- 
able economic  or  physical  connection  to  the  output  with  which  they 
are  associated.  While  practical  considerations  require  their  alloca- 
tion, the  guides  themselves  are  not  sufficient.  Within  wide  hmits 
set  by  custom,  allocations  are  molded  to  show  particular  results  for 
the  particular  purposes  of  the  allocater. 

In  making  the  allocations  the  .overpowering  tendency-  is  to  use 
accounting  procedures  which  wiU  place  costs  on  the  books  when  there 
is  output  and  receipts'  against  which  to  charge  them.  A  variety  of 
reasons  on  the  part  of  management  may  explain  this — reluctance  to 
a"dopt  accounting  methods  which  might  show  large  losses  in  poor 
year?,  efforts  tp  minimize  tax  liabilities,  desire  to  allocate  building  and 
equipment  expenses  as  equslly  as  possible  over  aU  units  of  output, 
and  so  forth.  Taken  together,  these  underlying  motives  operate  (a) 
to  minimize  the  fixed  costs,  (6)  to  raise  the  variable  costs,  and,  (c) 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13699 

to  show  constant  marginal  costs,  when  comparisons  between  book 
cost  and  output  are  made.     Thus,  the  true  picture  is  distorted. 

There  is  another  tendency  underlying  ordinary  costing  which  leads 
in  the  same  direction.  Some  choice  as  to  timing  exists  for  certain 
types  of  expenditures.  The  tendency  is  to  vary  such  expenditures  with 
the  volume  of  receipts.  At  the  same  time,  there  is  the  tendency  to 
charge  them  to  current  operations,  to  consider  them  sunk  costs,  the 
sooner  off  the  books  the  better. 

The  effect  of  the  particular  accounting  procedures  used  upon  the 
results  obtained  from  a  study  of  over-all  cost-volume  such  as  the 
Corporation's  is  so  great  that  it  cannot  be  neglected.  In  fact,  it  may 
be  said  that  the  accounting  procedures  themselves  are  major  determi- 
nants of  the  statistico-arithmetic  results.  Particular  consideration 
must  be  given  to  the  allocations  of  charges  as  between  years  since  it 
is  the  shape  of  the  cost  curve  which  expresses  whether  unit  costs 
increase,  decrease,  or  remain  constant  with  increases  in  output.  While 
(a)  the  items  included  in  cost  and  (6)  the  total  amounts  of  those  items 
charged  to  costs  over  the  life  of  the  business  are  also  factors,  yet  they 
do  not  loom  large  in  comparison  with  the  allocation  of  the  items 
included  as  between  years,  particularly  in  an  analysis  such  as  the 
Corporation's  in  which  practically  all  expenditures  are  included.  I 
shall  not  discuss  these  two  elements;  partly  because  they  do  not 
appear  impc  rtant,  but  also  because  the  published  sources  provide 
no  adequate  material  for  determining  their  effect  upon  the  cost- 
volume  analysis. 

The  chief  items  subject  to  allocation  over  accounting  periods  are 
depreciation,  depletion,  amortization,  maintenance,  repairs,  in- 
tangibles such  as  patents,  and  similar  items.  Clearly  when  such 
expenditures  are  actually  charged  to  costs  is  just  as  important  as  how 
much  is  charged  to  costs.  That  the  Corporation  has  in  the  past 
made  serious  errors  in  the  timing  of  the  charges  is  indicated  by  the 
establishment  in  1935  of  a  "Reserve  for  amortization  of  investments 
in  subsidiaries"  of  181  milhon  dollars.  This  reserve  was  established, 
presumably,  because  of  the  undercharging  of  depreciation  in  the 
period  prior  to  1935.  In  1935  and  later  years  the  reserve  is  drawn 
upon  to  increase  current  profit  figures— about  $7,000,000  in  1936  and 
$8,000,000  in  1937.  Thus,  when  "costs"  are  shifted  as  between  years 
the  results  of  a  cost-volume  analysis  are  different  from  those  which 
might  have  been  obtained  had  such  shifting  not  been  indulged  in. 

The  periods  to  which  expenditures  are  charged  as  costs  are  some- 
times the  result  of  advanced  planning,  such  planning  being  based  upon 
the  estimated  Hfe  of  assets,  the  estimated  output  or  both.  Errors  in 
such  estimates  are  corrected  by  adjustment  on  the  books  as  they  are 
recognized.  Final  adjustment  always  occurs  at  the  time  of  disposal 
of  the  assets.  For  it  is  only  upon  final  liquidation  that  actual  costs 
are  known.  Business,  however,  must  make  interim  estimates;  hence 
the  errors. 

The  method  of  handling  such  adjustments  is,  however,  extremely 
important  if  the  figures  are  to  be  used  for  an  analysis  of  costs.  Typi- 
cally, a  revision  of  cost  figures  for  prior  years  is  not  made  by  revising 
the  figures  for  the  earlier  years  but  by  adjusting  the  figures  for  the 
current  year.  This  may  not  be  a  serious  matter  if  the  adjustment  is 
not  included  as  an  item  of  current  costs  but  as  an  adjustment  to 
surplus.     But,  if  the  adjustment  is  charged  to  current  costs  (or  spread 


13700  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

over  current  and  future  costs),  any  cost- volume  analysis  based  on 
them  will  be  seriously  warped. 

The  Corporation's  method  of  handling  one  type  of  adjustment  is 
indicated  in  the  annual  report  for  1928,  which  states  that — 

The  large  increase  in  the  provisional  allowances  by  subsidiary  companies  in 
1928,  compared  with  1927,  is  attributable  to  a  considerable  extent  to  the  rather 
substantial  amounts  charged  off  for  obsolescence  of  property  investment  cost  in 
connection  with  abandonment  of  old  plants  not  theretofore  fully  depreciated. 

Thus,  what  might  be  construed  as  an  adjustment  for  inadequate 
depreciation  prior  to  1928  became  an  operating  charge  in  1928. 

An  interesting  discussion  of  the  extent  to  which  the  United  States 
Steel  Corporation  erred  in  computing  profits  and,  therefore,  costs  during 
the  twenties  is  contained  in  a  paper  by  W.  A.  Hosmer,  in  "Business  and 
Modern  Society",  published  by  the  Harvard  University  Press  in  1938. 
I  refer  those  who  are  interested  in  further  study  of  the  matter  to 
Professor  Hosmer's  very  excellent  paper. 

In  the  ultimate  analysis,  because  of  the  discretionary  elements  of 
all  cost  allocation,  everything  that  may  be  shown  by  the  cost-volume 
relation  is  explicitly  or  implicitly  assumed  by  the  accounting  proced- 
ures as  appropriate.  It  is  impossible  to  demonstrate  that  any  par- 
ticular allocation  is  most  vali'^  except  for  a  particular  purpose.  All 
that  we  can  show  is  that  a  particular  method  of  allocation  gives  a 
particular  :Lelation  between  charges  to  costs  and  volume.  This  is 
what  the  Corporation's  analysis  shows  at  most,  for  example,  for 
depreciation  and  depletion. 

The  sources  upon  which  my  analysis  is  based  are  (1)  the  Corpora- 

tion's 
annual  reports,  and  (3)  the  Corporation's  registration  statement 
filed  with  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission.  I  am  convinced, 
however,  that  the  essential  nature  of  my  conclusions  would  not  be 
changed  had  I  had  acces's  to  the  sources  at  the  disposal  of  the  Corpora- 
tion's analysts. 

In  order  to  bring  out  most  clearly  the  full  effect  of  the  arbitrary 
nature  of  cost  allocation  and  classification,  I  have  cast  my  analysis 
within  the  same  general  statistical  framework  as  that  used  by  the 
Corporation.  In  so  doing,  I  do  not  imply  that  that  framework  is 
above  criticism.  In  this  connection,  the  following  observations  are, 
I  think,  pertinent. 

1,  I  have  used  the  Corporation's  own  measurements  of  output, 
i.  e.,  the  Corporation's  own  figures  on  weighted  tons  of  products 
shipped,  though  I  do  not  admit  the  validity  of  the  methods  used  to 
devise  them.  The  principal  defects  of  these- measurements  for  pur- 
poses of  cost  analysis  revolve  around  the  weights  used  to  convert 
quantities  of  a  wide  variety  of  different  products  into  homogeneous 
units  of  output  and  the  lack  of  consideration  given  to  changes  in 
capacity  during  the  period  covered. 

2.  Though  I  do  not  admit  the  validity  of  the  particular  applica- 
tion, I  have  used  the  least  squares  or  correlation  technique,  though 
perhaps  not  with  the  same  degree  of  excellence  as  the  Corporation's 
analysts,  for  deriving  the  sum.mary  relation  between  a  cost  category 
and  volume,  and  have  labeled  the  statistical  results  (technically  esti- 

'  AppendU.p.  14032. 


tion's  study  entitled,  "An  Analysis  of  Steel  Prices,  Volume  and  Cc 
I  believe  identified  as  "Exhibit  No.  1416,"  '  (2)  the  Corpora ti 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13701 

mates  of  parameters)  as  "fixed"  and  "variable"  costs  in  the  same 
manner  as  has  the  Corporation.  The  principal  defect  of  the  technique 
is  that  it  takes  no  account  of  the  interdependence  of  the  cost  measure- 
ments for  the  various  years.  This  defect  is  extremely  critical.  Be- 
cause it  exists  in  the  technique,  no  account  is  taken  of  such  facts  as 
this:  If  depreciation  is  charged  to  costs  in  one  year,  it  cannot  be 
charged  in  another  year  so  that  relatively  high  charges  in  one  year 
tend  to  involve  relatively  low  charges  in  another  year. 

3.  I  have  not  attempted  to  measure  the  effects  of  such  inadequacies 
as  may  exist  in  the  Corporation's  adjustments  of  pay-roll  and  "other 
expenses"  to  "1938  conditions."  The  pay-roll  adjustment  as  made 
takes  no  direct  account  of  the  possible  effects  upon  average  hourly 
wage  rates  of  differences  in  the  proportions  of  employees  in  the  vari- 
ous occupations  at  different  outputs.  Furthermore,  the  facts  upon 
which  the  adjustment  for  increasing  labor  efficiency  was  made  seem 
more  appropriately  to  indicate  (a)  declining  unit  labor  cost  with  the 
expansion  m  output  during  1927-29  and  1934-37,  and  (6)  inadequate 
allowance  for  changing  compositions  of  the  working  force  during 
1930-33.  With  regard  to  "other  expenses"  it  seems  pertinent  at 
least  to  raise  the  question  as  to  whether  a  somewhat  modified  general 
index  of  prices  is  appropriate  for  deflating  the  amounts  paid  by  the 
Corporation  for  what  must  be  a  rather  specific  composition  of  goods 
and  services. 

That  the  purpose  for  which  accounting  statements  are  made  de- 
termines, in  part,  the  way  in  which  expenditures  and  charges  are 
classified  can  be  illustrated  by  contrasting  the  segregation  of  accounts 
for  public  statement  purposes  with  the  segregation  of  accounts  for 
the  cost  analysis. 

I  have  six  tables.     Shall  I  insert  them  one  by  one? 

Dr.  Kreps.  Would  you  prefer  to  insert  them  as  a  group  at  this 
time? 

Mr.  Taitel.  I  believe  that  would  be  most  convenient. 

Dr.  Kreps.  Mr.  Chairman,  I  should  like  to  insert  into  the  record  a 
series  of  six  tables  titled  as  follows:  Table  I,  "Reconcihation  of  Total 
Costs  Before  Bond  Interest  and  Inter-Company  Items  in  .'Analysis' 
and  Registration  Statement,  1935-37"";  Table  II,  "Comparison  of 
Break-Down  of  Lumped  Costs  in  the  'Analysis'  and  in  Registration 
Statement,  1935-37";  Table  II-A,  "Additions  to  Reserves  Charged  to 
Cost  of  Goods  Sold,  Etc.,  1935-37";  Table  III,  '  Taxes  Other  Than 
Federal  Income  and  Social  Security  Taxes,  1927-38";  Table  IV, 
"Taxes  Other  Than  Federal  Income  and  Social  Security  Taxes,  1927- 
38 — Recom.puted  'Fixed'  and  'Variable'  Costs";  Table  V,  "Mainte- 
nance and  Repairs,  1927-38";  Table  VI,  Stripping  and  Development 
Experises,  1927-38". 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  Who  prepared  these  charts? 

Mr.  Taitel.  I  prepared  these  tables. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  And  the  source  of  the  material? 

Mr.  Taitel.  The  sources  are  indicated  on  the  table.  They  have 
been  taken  from  the  three  general  sources  I  indicated,  the  Cost 
Volume  Analysis,  the  annual  reports,  and  the  registration  statement. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  They  will  be  admitted. 

(The  tables  referred  to  were  marked  "Exliibit  No.  2185"  and  are 
included  in  the  appendix  on  p.  14121.) 


13702       OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Mr.  Taitel.  a  reconciliation  of  the  figures  in  the  Corporation's 
"Analysis"  with  those  in  the  S.  E.  C.  registration  statement  for  the 
three  years  1935-37  is  shown  in  Table  I  of  the  group  of  tables  iden- 
tified as  "Exliibib  No.  2185."  To  obtain  the  same  total  costs,  (1) 
"Expenses  for  dismantling,  moving,  and  rearranging  of  existing  facil- 
ities, less  the  value  of  salvage  recovered  in  connection  therewith"  have 
to  be  omitted  although  classified  as  operating  expenses  in  the  registra- 
tion statement;  (2)  "Plant  and  organization  survey  expenses"  have 
to  be  included  although  classified  as  an  income  deduction  in  the  regis- 
tration statement;  and  (3)  "Discoimt  on  purchases"  has  to  be  in- 
cluded although  classified  as  other  income  in  the  registration  statement 
and  annual  reports. 

In  the  annual  reports  and  registration  statement  there  is  a  functional 
classification  of  accoimts.  Cost  of  goodi-sold,  and  so  forth  (including 
intercompany  items),  apparently  includes  all  items  which  are  con- 
strued to  be  allocable  to  specific  items  of  output.  Thus,  certain 
amortization,  rents  and  royalties,  and  maintenance  and  repairs,  are 
charged  directly  to  cost  of  goods  sold.  At  times,  also,  certain  taxes 
(in  minor  amounts)  have  been  so  charged.  Included  also,  are  gross 
operating  expenditures  for  transportation  and  miscellaneous  operations 
(both  shown  separately  at  times). 

Another  general  functional  category  is  "Other  operating  expenses" 
which  apparently  covers  items  which  are  not  deemed  to  be  specifically 
alloc9.ble  to  items  of  output.  Presumably,  only  steel  operations  are 
covered.  The  major  items  are  (1)  general  administrative  and  selling 
expense?,  (2)  depreciation  and  depletion,  and  (3)  taxes. 

Finally,  there  is  a  third  functional  classification — "other  income" 
and  "income  deductions."  This  includes  items  apparently  considered 
to  be  nonoperating  in  character,  such  as  dividends,  rents  and  royalties, 
capital  losses,  and  so  forth. 

In  the  Corporation's  cost  analysis  the  classification  of  accounts 
used  for  public  statement  purposes  is  retained  only  in  part.  The 
bulk  of  the  costs  are  redistributed  into  two  classifications:  (1)  Pay 
roU,  and  (2)  other  expenses.  It  was  not  possible  for  me  to  recast 
them  along  functional  lines  since  the  Corporation's  public  statements 
do  not  contain  the  necessary  data.  It  was  possible,  however,  to  indi- 
cate the  character  of  some  of  the  items  included  in  the  two  categories. 
This  is  shown  in  Tables  II  and  II-A^  where  the  two  types  of  break- 
downs are  compared. 

The  two  bases  of  classification  are  not  contradictory;  they  are 
just  different.  And  the  reason  they  are  different  lies  largely  in  the 
different  purposes  for  which  the  Corporation  has  prepared  them. 

That  the  Corporation  has  made  an  inadequate  division  between 
fixed  and  variable  costs,  even  in  teims  of  its  own  analysis,  is  clearly 
illustrated  by  the  treatment  accorded  in  the  cost  anatysis  to  taxes 
other  than  Federal  income  and  social  security  taxes.  This  tax  item 
includes  mainly  State  and  local  property  taxes  but  also  the  Federal 
capital  stock  and  excise  and  miscellaneous  taxes.  The  break-do\\Ti 
is  shown  in  Table  III  of  "Exhibit  No.  2185."  For  some  years  the  tax 
figures  apparently  represent  the  accrual  of  tax  liabilities  and  the 
difference  column  indicates  the  extent  of  allocation  as  between  years. 

Capital  stock  taxes  should  not  have  been  lumped  with  the  other 
taxes.     The  Corporation  was  not  subject  to  such  taxes  prior  to  1982.. 

•  Of  "Exhibit  No.  2186,"  appendix,  pp.  14121  and  14122. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13703 

SO  that  they  should  at  least  have  been  segregated.  But  most  impor- 
tant is  the  fact  that  capital  stock  taxes  under  "1938  conditions" 
depend,  not  upon  output,  but  upon  decisions  by  management  based 
upon  «5«timates  not  only.of  future  costs  but  also  of  future  output  and 
prices.  Stated  otherwise,  declared  values  for  tax  purposes  are  deter- 
mined within  limits  by  management  forecasts  of  net  incomes,  i.  e., 
the  estimated  relation  between  costs  and  receipts;  they  are  not 
determinants  of  net  incomes  in  the  sense  in  which  a  property  tax  is. 
Thus,  reduction  to  "1938  conditions"  for  purposes  of  a  cost  analysis 
imphes  that  the  1938  figure  should  best  be  used  for  all  years,  i.  e., 
that  the  capital  stock  tax  is  probably  best  considered  as  a  fixed  cost. 
The  contention  might  be  made  (and  to  some  extent  is  implicit  in  the 
Corporation's  analysis)  that  declared  values  would  s^ary  with  output. 
But  this  assumes  that  prices  will  vary  with  output  in  such  a  way 
as  to  make  it  profitable  for  the  Corporation  to  vary  the  declared  values 
with  output.  Realistically,  such  an  assumption,  not  to  mention  the 
assumption  of  accurate  forecasting,  has  no  place  in  a  cost  analysis, 
particularly  one  for  the  Corporation  in  view  of  the  fact  that  in  1938 
a  greater  tax  was  allocated  to  costs  than  in  1937. 

Appropriate  treatment  of  the  capital  stock  tax  would  destroy  what 
Uttle  reliability  there  is  in  the  analysis  of  taxes  on  pages  13-14  of  the 
Corporation's  analysis. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Whaf  exhibit? 

Mr.  Taitel.  "Exhibit  No.  1416."  They  account  for  a  good  share 
of  the  rise  in  taxes  between  1932  and  1938  as  the  figures  in  Table  IV 
of  "Exhibit  No.  2185"-  show.  Exclusive  of  capital  stock*  taxes  there 
is  no  significant  difference  between  the  relation  of  taxes  and  weighted 
tons  for  1932-38  and  the  relation  for  1927-31.  The  $43,200,000  item 
for  1937  is  the  most  extreme  observation,  being  about  15  percent 
above  the  next  largest  one.  This  suggest?  not  a  shift  in  the  tax 
burden  between  the  two  periods,  but  rather  some  peculiarity  in  the 
1937  tax  charges. _ 

The  effect  of  using  tax  figures  appropriate  for  general-statement  pur- 
poses, but  not  appropriate  for  cost-volume  relations,  upon  the  results 
of  the  Corporation's  analysis  is  substantial.  Results  of  a  recomputa- 
tion  of  the  tax  regression  both  including  and  excluding  1937  data  are 
shown  in  Table  IV  of  "Exhibit  No.  2185."  Capital-stock  taxes  have 
been  considered  as  a  fixed  cost  at  the  1938  level. 

Both  of  the  recomputations  show  a  much  higher  "fixed"  and  a  much 
lower  "variable"  tax  cost  than  is  shown  by  the  Corporation's  analysis. 
Even  with  the  1937  observation  included,  "fixed"  costs  are  raised  by 
almost  25  percent  and  "variable"  costs  lowered  by  over  50  percent 
with  reference  to  the  results  of  the  Corporation's  analysis.  The  recom- 
putation  excluding  1937  shows  "fixed"  costs  to  be  raised  almost  30 
percent  and  "variable"  costs  lowered  almost  65  percent. 

A  study  of  the  maintenance  and  repair  expenditures  of  the  Corpo- 
ration shown  in  Table  V  of  "Exhibit  No.  2185"  illustrates  the  tendency 
of  the  Corporation  to  charge  some  expenditures  to  costs  when  made. 
It  also  provides  another  illustration  of  the  effects  of  an  inadequate 
segregation  of  costs  upon  the  results  of  a  statistical  cost  analysis.  In 
this  latter  case  it  is  the  Corporation's  treatment  of  maintenance  on 
railroad  properties  which  may  be  suitable  for  some  purposes  of  the 
Corporation  but  which  is  definitely  misleading  for  purposes  of  coat 
analysis. 


13704  OONOENTRATION  OF  ECJONOMIC  POWER 

The  bulk  of  the  maintenance  and  repair  expenditures  (all  in  the  case 
of  railroad  properties)  are  charged  to  costs  as  made,  although  small 
portions  are  passed  through  reserves  each  year.  By  and  large,  how- 
ever, maintenance  is  charged  as  the  work  is  done — not  when  the  par- 
ticular outputs  making  maintenance  necessary  occurred.  Further- 
more, no  segregation  appears  in  the  published  sources  (except  to  a 
very  limited  extent  in  the  registration  statement)  between  maintenance 
required  regardless  of  output  and  the  additional  amounts  of  mainte- 
nance required  for  each  level  of  output.  And  in  the  cost  analysis, 
maintenance  is  presumably  buried  in  pay-roll  and  other  expenses — 
although  the  figures  are  available — even  though  the  amounts  charged 
to  costs  in  some  years  have  been  almost  twice  as  great  as  depreciation 
and  depletion. 

Included  in  the  maintenance  and  repair  accounts  of  the  Corporation 
are  the  expenditures  on  lis  railroad  properties  which  are  always 
charged  to  costs  when  made.  But  all  of  the  operating  and  maiate- 
nance  expenses  of  its  railroads  should  not  be  included  in  those  costs 
which  are  presumably  comparable  with  steel  shipments.  (For  a 
wider  range  of  factors  this  point  is  discussed  and  carefully  minimized 
in  the  Corporation's  analysis,  pp.  39-42,  "Exhibit  No.  1416.")  Part 
of  the  other  transportation  and  miscellaneous  operajtions  should 
also  be  excluded.  But  it  was  not  possible  to  do'so  since  the  necessary 
accounts  are  not  shown  separately  in  the  annual  reports.  However, 
other  than  railroad  maintenance  charges  are  relatively  minor  items — 
they  only  accounted  for  ibout  3  percent  of  the  total  maintenance 
expenditures  in  1929,  wh  reas  railroad  transportation  accounted  for 
about  20  percent. 

The  allocation  of  practically  all  maintenance  and  repair  expendi- 
tures to  costs  in  the  year  in  which  they  occur  is  improper.  There 
is,  of  course,  a  considerable  amount  of  leeway  as  to  when  such  expendi- 
tures are  made.  That  the  Corporation's  practice  reflects  the  element 
of  flexibility  is  indicated  in  the  1932  annual  report  which  says  that 
"maintenance  expenditures  *  *  *  include  a  substantial  amount 
expended  m  order  to  keep  inactive  departments  prepared  for  resurnp- 
tion  of  operations  when  business  improves."  Thus,  the  Corporation 
charged  to  1932  costs,  maintenance  expenditures  which  it  admits 
were  necessary  either  on  account  of  past  or  future  operations  but 
not  to  current  operations.  And  it  should  be  noted  that  only  a  very 
small  part  ($469,000  out  of  $28,000,000)  of  the  current  expenditures 
were  not  charged  to  current  costs,  while  $1,300,000  was  charged  to 
current  costs  to  build  up  the  reserve  account. 

Application  of  the  statistical  technic  used  in  the  Corporation's 
cost  analysis  to  the  maintenance  and  repair  data  gives  the  following 
results: 


"FUed" 

costs  per 

year 

"Variable- 
costs 
per  ton 

Coefficient 
of  cor- 
relation 

Total  (1927-38) 

$5,320,000 
1,600,000 
3,720,000 

$8,356 
6.320 
2.036 

0.08 

Excluding  railroads  (1927-36) 

.97 

Railroads  (by  subtraction)                              ' — 

. 

GONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13705 

No  adjustments  have  been  made  for  wage  and  price  changes  similar 
to  those  in  the  analysis.  Such  adjustments  would  tend  somewhat 
to  raise  the  "fixed"  and  lower  the  "variable"  costs. 

If  my  analysis  of  maintenance  and  repair  expenditures  presented 
thus  far  is  correct  the  Corporation's  analysis  is  biased  to  the  following 
extent: 

1.  "Variable"  costs  are  overstated  between  $1  and  $2  per  ton 
because  of  the  inclusion  of  railroad  maintenance  exp^iditures  in 
excess  of  those  "attributable"  to  shipments. 

2.  "Fixed"  costs  are  understated  by  the  inclusion  of  the  total 
railroad  maintenance  expenditures. 

The  results  indicate  that  the  Corporation  has  practically  adopted 
the  "cost  when  spent"  principle  for  maintenance.  They  also  indicate 
that  the  Corporation  has  come  close  in  its  maintenance  accounting 
to  the  principle  of  spreading  such  costs  equally  over  all  units  of  output. 
Had  "equal  spreading"  been  fiUly  accomplished,  the  "variable"  cost 
computations  for  mamtenance  excluding  railroads  would  have  been 
lower  by  about  10  cents  per  ton  than  the  $6.32  figure  obtained.  The 
two  figures  are  so  close  as  to  warrant  the  suspicion  that  they  are  the 
results  of  a  conscious  design. 

The  Corporation's  policies  with  regard  to  depreciation  and  depletion, 
as  stated  in  its  S.  E.  C.  registration  statement,  are — 

1.  Depreciation  is  charged  on  the  straight-line  method.  When 
the  actual  operating  rate  is  less  than  the  predetermined  average 
rate  charges  are  reduced  but  less  than  proportionately  ahd  in  no  case 
by  more  than  50  percent.  (Railroad  equipment  is,  of  'course,  depre- 
ciated at  rates  approved  by  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission.) 

2.  Depletion  is  charged  by  prorating  the  investment  costs  over  the 
estimated  recoverable  quantitj^. 

The  Corporation's  policy  with  regard  to  depreciation  is  only  one 
of  many  that  might  have  been  followed,  and  is  apparently  a  com- 
promise between  charging  equal  amounts  per  unit  and  equal  amounts 
per  annum.  On  an  equal  charge  basis,  the  statistical  computations 
would  show  an  annual  "fixed"  cost  of  about  53  million  dollars  but 
no  "variable"  cost;  on  an  equal  per  unit  charge  basis,  the  computa- 
tions would  show  no  "fixed"  costs  but  a  "variable"  cost  of  about 
$5.30  per  weighted  ton.  It  is  easily  seen  that  the  actual  results  of 
29.5  milUon  dollars  for  "fLxed"  and  2.37  for  "variable"  costs  obtained 
by  the  Corporation  are  about  halfway  between  these  two  extremes. 

Our  analysis  assumes,  of  course,  that  the  depreciation  and  deple- 
tion figures  which  the  Corporation  uses  in  its  cost  analysis  are  the 
appropriate^  ones  in  the  sense  that  they  are  computed  in  accordance 
with  a  general  pohcy  that  does  not' change  from  year  to  year.  But 
the  records  at  my  disposal  indicate  that  this  may  not  be  so. 

(Senator  King  assumed  the  Chair.) 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Depreciation  and  depletion,  especially  in 
mines,  that  is  largely  fixed  by  statute. 

Mr.  Taitel.  It  is  fixed  by  statute  in  terms  of  statements  for  tax 
purposes.  It  is  not  fixed  by  statute  in  terms  of  what  corporations 
may  charge  on  their  own  books  for  their  own  purposes. 

Both  the  1927  and  1928  depreciation  figures  in  the  Corporation's 
cost  analysis  include  about  11.5  million  dollars, of  charges  to  a  bond 


13706       OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

sinking  fund  reserve  used  "to  cover  amortization  of  appreciated  cost 
to  it  (the  holding  company)  of  investment  in  stocks  of  subsidiary- 
companies  in  excess  of  their  own  investment  in  tangible  property." 
Such  charges  were  made  in  years  prior  to  1929  but  not  in  later  years. 
It  is  not  clear  whether  these  charges  simply  make  up  for  under-depre- 
ciation  on  the  books  of  the  subsidiaries,  i.  e.,  represent  the  basis 
for  transfers  in  excess  of  earnings  from  the  subsidiaries  to  the  holding 
company  in  order  to  fulfill  the  conditions  of  the  bond  indenture,  or 
whether  they  are  bona  fide  amortizations  of  intangibles  by  the  hold- 
ing company.  Just  how  these  amounts  should  have  been  handled  in 
the  cost  analysis  depends,  of  course,  upon  the  continuity  of  depre- 
ciation policy  during  this  period. 

Also  included  in  depreciation  were  charges  of  about  $1,000,000  in 
1932,  $400,000  in  1933,  $450,000  in  1934,  a^d  $400,000  in  1935 
"normally  included  in  the  value  of  the  season's  production  of  ore 
carried  in  'inventories'."  These  charges  belong,  of  course,  in  other 
accounts.  However,  their  inclusion  in  the  depreciation  account  has 
only  a  minor  effect  on  the  statistical  results. 

Conversely,  about  7  million  dollars  in  1936,  8  million  in  1937,  and 
probably  a  somewhat  smaller  amount  in  1938  were  excluded  from  the 
depreciation  item  included  in  the  cost  analysis.  These  amounts  rep- 
resent charges  against  a  special  reserve  set  up 'in  1935  on  the  books 
of  the  holding  company  presumably  to  make  up  under-depreciation 
in  prior  years.  The  extent  to  which  changes  in  depreciation  rates 
occurred  is  not  clear. 

The  depreciation  and  depletion  figures  used  in  the  cost  analysis  do 
not  include  a  comparable  item  for  amortizing  "investment  in  strip- 
ping and  development  of  mines  and  structural  erection  equipment." 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Do  not  take  into  account  the  credit  to 
which  they  would  be  entitled  in  their  balance  sheet? 

Mr.  Taitel.  What  I  am  saying  is  that  the  depreciation  and  deple- 
tion figures  used  in  the  Corporation's  analysis  as  depreciation  and 
depletion  figures  do  not  include  the  item  on  the  books  of  the  Corpora'- 
tion  for  investment  in  stripping  and  development  of  mines  and  in 
structural  erection  equipment.  Those  expenses  are  not  included  in 
the  Corporation's  analysis  under  the  item  of  depreciation  and  deple- 
tion. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Would  that  be  to  their  advantage  m 
obtaining  offsets? 

Mr.  Taitel.  Well,  they  are  charged  or  entered  as  costs  on  their 
books,  but  they  are  in  separate  accounts.  The  cost  analysis,  having 
taken  the  depreciation  figures,  as  I  understand  it,  from  the  annual 
reports,  does  not  include  the  stripping  and  development  ejqpenses, 
and  the  structural  erection  equipment  expenditures.  The  item  is 
charged  directly  to  property  accounts  and  not  through  reserves. 

The  Corporation's  policy  with  regard  to  this  item  is,  according  to 
the  registration  statement,  to  charge  the  strij-ping  and  development 
part  to  cost  in  the  same  manner  as  depletion,  and  the  structural  erec- 
tion equipment  part  in  the  same  manner  as  depreciation.  Another 
indication  of  the  depreciation  and  depletion  character  of  the  item  are 
the  wide  differences  from  year  to  year  between  expenditures  and 
charges  to  costs  shown  in  table  VI  of  "Exhibit  No.  2185." 


OONOENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER       13707 

No  doubt  the  Corporation  has  reasons  which  are  valid  in  terms  of 
operating  and  related  purposes  for  not  handling  the  stripping  and 
development  expenses  as  depreciation  and  depletion. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  VMiere  would  you  place  upon  the  books 
that  you  were  keeping  the  cost  for  stripping  and  for  depreciation? 
^Vhat  column  would  you  put  those  costs  in? 

Mr.  Taitel.  The  iuetlvod  of  accounting  which  the  Corporation  uses 
in  handhng  its  stripping  and  development  expenses  is  a  perfectly  good 
one.  The  only  difference  between  that  method  and  the  method  used 
for  the  regular  depreciation  and  depletion  accoimt  is  this:  When  an 
expenditure  is  made  for  stripping  and  developing,  it  is  entered  directly 
as  an  investment;  when  a  charge  is  made  to  costs,  the  amount  is 
entered  in  the  same  investment  account,  instead  of  in  a  separate 
depreciation  or  depletion  account. 

I  do  not  intend  to  imply  that  the  Corporation  is  using  bad  accounting 
practices.  It  is  a  perfectly  legitmiate  procedure  and  the  procedure 
is  stated  very  clearly  in  the  annual  reports. 

Mr.  Walter  White,  You  mean  by  that  that  they  charge  stripping 
expense,  for  instance,  to  ore  that  is  being  mined  from  somewhere  else, 
in  the  current  year,  instead  of  to  the  ore  which  will  be  mined  under- 
neath that  stripping  in  a  subsequent  year? 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Perhaps  the  question  is  not  clear.  Will 
you  repeat  it? 

Mr.  Walter  White.  ^Vhether  the  stripping  is  charged,  or  the 
stripping  over  a  certain  ore  body  is  charged  to  operating  expense,  in 
connection  with  oie  receipts  from  somewhere  else — that  is,  that  year's 
operation  is  not  held  in  a  suspense  account  to  be  charged  against  it, 
or  wliich  underlies  the  particular  body  o^  ore  that  is  being  stripped?  • 

Mr.  Taitel.  As  I  understand  the  accounting  procedure,  as  the 
annual  report  states  it,' when  they  make  an  expenditure  for  stripping, 
they  charge  it  to  the  property  account,  that  is,  it  is  an  addition  to  the 
property  asset,  it  is  an  investment.  In  essence,  it  is  -a  suspense 
account,  as  you  put  it.  Later,  when  the  ore  is  mined,  it  is  charged 
to  the  ore  mined. 

Mr,  Walter  White.  I  should  think  that  would  be  the  proper  or 
usual  practice. 

Mr.  Taitel.  I  don't  know  whether  it  is  the  usual  practice.  I 
simply  state  that  that  is  what  the  Corporation  does. 

But  whatever  the  reasons  for  so  doing,  those  reasons  cannot  justify 
the  treatment  of  stripping  and  development  expenses  in  the  Corpora- 
tion's cost  analysis.  Particularly  should  the  item  have  been  segregated 
in  the  cost  analysis  since  it  is  included  in  "Other  Exisenses,"  a  cost 
category  treated  in  the  cost  analysis  as  if  it  represented  current  pur- 
chases of  goods  and  services. 

The  "variable"  cost  for  stripping,  and  so  forth,  is  higher  by  about 
14  cents  per  weighted  ton  than  the  over  all  average  of  40  cents  for  the 
12  years.  This  does  not  indicate  a  close  correspondence  with  a  poUcy 
of  allocation  directed  toward  obtaining  equal  per  unit  costs,  but  rather 
a  tendency  on  the  part  of  the  Corporation  to  charge  larger  amoimts 
T^er  unit  the  larger  the  output  and  the  income  realized.  In  view  of 
such  a  tendency,  it  may  be  said  that  the  particular  treatment  accorded 
to  stripping  and  related  expenses  biases  the  "variable"  cost  derived 
in  the  Corporation's  analysis  slightly,  upward  and  the  "fixed"  cost 
slightly  downward. 

124491— 41— pt.  26 9 


13708  OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Criticisms  of  the  nature  presented  do  not,  of  course,  negate  the 
hard  facts  of  total  costs.  In  the  long  run,  cumulated  total  costs  as 
they  appear  in  the  income  account  as  charges  approximate  actual 
cumulative  money  costs.  And  over  a  long  period  of  time,  money 
costs  are  determinative.  They  must  be  met  by  receipts  if  a  profit 
is  to  be  made  and  if  the  Corporation  is  to, remain  in  business.  But 
this  is  true  only  in  the  so-called  long  run.  In  the  short-run  periods, 
and  it  is  in  the  short  run  that  prices  are  made,  total  costs  as  figured  in 
the  Corporation's  analysis  are  not  the  facts  upon  which  pricing  is 
based. 

Nor  is  the  implication  that  a  cost-volume  relation  pertinent  to 
pricing  would  have  been  obtained  had  more  appropriate  treatment 
been  accorded  to  the  various  cost  items  mentioned.  Rather,  with 
regard  to  the  technical  features  of  the  criticism  our  examination  of 
the  figures  upon  which  the  Corporation's  analysis  rests  has  shown  that, 
in  terms  of  the  Corporation's  own  framework  of  analysis — the 
applicability  of  which  to  the  problem  I  have  grave  doubts — the 
Corporation's  estimate  of  "fixed"  cost  is  biased  downward  and  the 
estimate  of  "variable"  cost  is  biased  upward. 

My  conclusion  with  regard  to  the  substantive  features  of  my  analysis 
is  that  a  division  between  fixed  and  variable  costs  obtained  from  a 
statistical  analysis  of  historical  data,  such  as  the  Corporation  has  made, 
bears  but  a  nebulous  relation  to  the  actual  division  of  fixed  and  variable 
costs  which  bears  upon  a  particular  act  of  pricing.  The  question 
may  fairly  be  raised  whether  the  Corporation  has  ever  before  had 
prepared  for  the  guidance  of  its  executives  cost  analyses  of  the  type 
presented  to  this  committee  for  the  purpose  of  helping  those  executives 
solve  tjieir  pricing  problems.  And  I  am  led  to  believe  that  the  Cor- 
poration's cost  analysis  is  not.  a  description  of  what  in  fact  has  guided 
its  pricing  policy  but  is  being  used  as  a  rationalization  of  the  actual 
pricing  practices  pursued  by  the  Corporation  in  the  past. 

It  is,  of  course,  possible  to  modify  the  statistical  analysis  used  by  the 
Corporation's  analysts  so  that  it  would  present  cost  schedules  relevant 
to  the  particular  pricing  problems  the  Corporation  faces.  Such 
modification,  however,  would  in  my  opinion  stop  little  short  of  destroy- 
ing the  whole  theoretical  basis  on  which  the  Corporation's  analysis 
rests.  But  it  would  provide  the  best  descriptive  measurements 
available  from  the  bag  of  tricks  of  modem  methodology. 

The  modification  would  be  based  upon  an  insistence  that  the  division 
between  fixed  and  variable  costs  or  a  cost-volume  relation  meaningful 
for  an  actual  price  decision  is  not  a  unique  relation  applicable  to  all 
possible  circumstances  and  therefore  to  none.  For  a  general  state- 
ment, the  most  appropriate  presentation  is  in  terms  of  upper  and  lower 
limits.  As  the  conditions  under  which  the  cost  figures  are  to  be  used 
converge  more  and  more  to  a  concrete  pricing  situation,  the  limits 
would  be  narrowed.  For  a  particular  pricing  situation,  the  range 
between  the  lower  and  upper  cost  estimates  can  probably  be  small 
enough  for  practical  purposes.  But  the  estimates  of  this  type  would 
bear  no  consistent  relation  to  the  Corporation's  cost-volume  curve. 

In  general,  the  lower  limit  for  a  cost  estimate  used  for  pricing  in 
connection  with  a  particular  prospective  volume — the  real  hard  cost 
that  must  be  covered  if  busniess  is  to  be  accepted— would  be  much 
below  the  one  indicated  by  the  Corporation's  analysis.     It  might  be 


OONOBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13709 

above.  But  where  it  would  fall  depends  upon  a  wide  range  of  practical 
circumstances,  such  as  the  condition  of  the  plant,  the  position  of 
material  suppliers,  the  degree  to  which  the  working  force  needs  to  be 
rearranged  for  production  at  the  contemplated  new  level,  and  so  on. 

The  upper  limit,  in  general,  would  be  above  the  cost-volume  curve 
of  the  Corporation's  analysis.  This  must  be  so  since  the  Corporation 
in  particular,  and  almost  any  business  in  general,  is  not  immune  from 
the  drive  to  cover  sunk  costs  as  quickly  as  possible.  For  a  general 
statement  applicable  to  a  whole  range  of  ordinary  practical  circum- 
stances, it  might  be  taken  as  the  minimum  amount  which  a  business 
must  cover  in  order  to  carry  on  over  a  very  long  period.  This  is 
roughly  equivalent  or  in  rough  conformance  with  accounting  princi- 
ples as  usually  stated  and  applied.  But  in  a  particular  pricing  situa- 
tion the  pertinent  upper  limit  of  costs  bears  no  necessary  or  consistent 
relation  to  the  generalized  upper  limit. 

In  brief  summary,  the  theoretical  calculations  submitted  by  the 
United  States  [Steely Corporation  analysts]!  would  regard  as  highly 
interesting  applications  of  refined  econometrics,  but  of  little  use  to  the 
committee  as  a  description  of  the  actual  considerations  upop  which 
steel  price  decisions  are  based. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Any  questions?  Thank  you  very  much, 
Professor. 

Call  your  next  witness,  Dr.  Kreps. 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  would  like  to  keep  Mr.  Taitel  on  the  stand.  While 
we  have  greatly  taxed  the  patience  of  Dr.  Yntema,  I  am  sure  he 
would  like  to  Inake  some  comments  on  Mr.  Taitel's  analysis,  reserving 
such  specific  questions  as  he  may  have  on  Dr.  Ezekiel's  analysis,"which 
Dr.  Ezekiel  ought  himseK  to  answer,  until  Friday  morning,  when  Dr. 
Ezekiel  can  be  back  in  town.  Unfortunately,  he  had  to  leave  at  4 
o'clock  this  afternoon.' 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Would  you  prefer  to  resume  the  stand 
now,  Doctor,  or  perhaps. you  would  rather  wait  until  the  morning? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  should  much  prefer  to  comment  on  this  tomorrow 
morning.  I  have  had  five  documents  to  read  and  this  is  the  first 
time  I  have  had  an  opportunity  to  hear  this  discussion.  I  could  deal 
with  the  general  aspects  of  it  now,  and  in  a  sense,  I  did  so  this  morning. 
But  I  think  that  my  comments  would  be  more  valuable  to  the  com- 
mittee if  I  could  make  them  to  morrow  morning. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  thirk  perhaps  that  would  be  better. 
>  Dr.  Kreps.  I  should  hke  to  point  out  to  the  chairman  that  the 
hearings  might  thereby  be  considerably  delayed.    We  have  a  witness 
for  tomorrow  morning  and  tomorrow  afternoon.    All  of  us  wou^d  like 
to' make  these  hearings  as  brief  as  possible. 

Dr.  Yntema  has  had  this  paper  '  since  yesterday.  As  he  has  him- 
self acknowledged,  he  made  some  comment  this  morning.  If  possible, 
and  if  it  does  not  transgress  on  his  patience  and  his  energy  too  much, 
he  would  really  help  us  to  keep  the  hearings  brief  if  he  could  make  his 
comnients  this  evening.     The  hour  is  still  early. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  think  if  the  witness  has  to  go  over  his 
paper  and  present  it^  then  if  you  ask  the  man  offhand  to  reply  to  it, 
I  think  you  ought  to  give  him  a  Uttle  more  time. 

'  Refers  to  a  prepared  statement  from  which  Mr.  Taitel  read. 


13710       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Dr.  Yntema.  Senator,  this  is  merely  the  point 

Acting  Chairman  King  (interposing).  And  there  would  be  no 
delay  as  far  as  the  committee  is  concerned.  If  it  would  not  delay  you , 
if  Dr.  Yntema  can  come  back 

Dr.  Yntema  (interposing).  I  can  make  comments  on  the  general 
question.  I  cannot  obviously,  on  such  short  notice,  comment  on 
highly  technical  points.  I  am  prepared  to  comment  both  on  Dr. 
Ezekiel's  paper  and  on  the  paper  which  Dr.  Bean  is  scheduled  to 
present.*     I  am  quite  willing  to  proceed  if  the  committee  so  desire. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Well,  if  you  are  wilb'ng  to  proceed,  if  you 
think  that  would  be  better,  that  you  would  make  a  better  presentation 
by  waiting  until  tomorrow,  as  far  as  the  chairman  is  concerned,  we 
won't  force  a  ^vitness  to  testify  when  he  isn't  quite  ready  to  testify. 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  general  point  to  which  I  should  address  myself 
would  be  this,  that  in  evaluating  criticism  which  has  been  offered  this 
afternoon — and  I  think  in  fairness,  we  should  say  this  is  a  scholarly 
statement  that  we  have  just  heard — in  evaluating  the  criticisms  which 
have  been  offered,  I  think  it  is  important  to  keep  in  mind  the  relative 
magnitude  of  the  various  parts  of  the  costs  and  the  portions  to  which 
these  comments  apply. 

As  I  pointed  out  in  the  discussion  this  morning  relative  to  table  8  of 
"Exhibit"  No.  1416,"  ^  there  are  two  major  elements  in  the  total  costs: 
The  pay  roll  and  the  "other  expenses."  With  reference  to  the  matter 
of  depreciation  and  depletion,  the  allocation  among  various  years  is, 
of  course,  arbitrary,  and  I  think  that  Mr.  Taitel  would  be  reluctant 
himself  to  specify  exactly  what  allocation  was  the  proper  one. 

With  reference  to  the  matter  of  maintenance  and  the  allocation  of 
these  other  costs  among  years,  the  propriety  of  the  allocation  depends 
eventually  upon  what  you  meaji  by  a  variable  cost  and  by  a  fixed  cost. 
From  one  point  of  view,  you  might  insist  that  those  maintenance  and 
repair  charges  should  be  allocated  equally  over  every  one  of  the  years. 
From  that  point  of  view,  they  would  all  become  fixed  costs.  Or  you 
might  say  that  they  should  all  be  allocated  in  proportion  to  the  volume 
of  output.  Or  you  might  say  that  they  should  be  allocated  in  such  a 
way  as  businessmen  do  allocate  them,  confronted  as  they  are  with  the 
ups  and  downs  of  business. 

Now,  the  last  is  substantially  the  definition  of  variable  costs  which 
we  have  used.  We  have  in  our  separation  of  costs  between  fixed  and 
variable,  attempted  to  adjust  as  best  we  could,  for  the  effects  of 
changes  in  the  wage  rates  and  the  prices  and  the  tax  rates,  which  the 
Corporation  must  pay  at  different  points  in  the  cycle.  We  have  at- 
tempted to  adjust  also  for  the  change  in  efficiency  as  reflected  by  the 
downward  trend  in  the  costs.  We  have  not  eliminated  such  in- 
equahty  in  the  distribution  of  maintenance  items  as  results  from  ad- 
justments to  the  ups  and  downs  in  volume  of  business,  and  I  submit 
to  the  committee  that  that  is  the  appropriate  treatment  of  the  item. 

I  should  take  issue  with  the  criticism  which  has  just  been  made, 
that  maintenance  cost  is  really  a  cost  which  ought  to  be  allocated 
equally  year  by  year  so  that  it  would  thereby  become  fixed  rather 
than  variable.  But  I  have  no  quarrel  with  that;  it  is  merely  a  matter 
of  definition  of  terms.  I  suggest  that  the  definition  I  used  was  the 
appropriate  one. 

'  Dr.  Bean's  testimony  begins  infre,  p.  13719. 
>  Apoendix,  p.  14040. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13711 

Acting  Chairman  King.  How  could  you  make  that  a  fixed  charge 
when  one  plant  with  the  same  uses  may  become  obsolete  in,  say,  5 
3^ears,  and  another  in  20  years?  How  could  you  say  that  that  should 
be  a  fixed  charge  and  should  be  the  same  during  that  entire  period? 

Dr.  Yntema.  My  opinion  is  that  we  have  handled  the  situation 
correctly  for  the  purpose  with  which  we  were  concerned,  namely,  a 
study  of  how  costs  fluctuated  in  the  business  cycle,  and  the  possibili- 
ties of  reduction  in  costs  in  the  cycle.  It  seems  to  me  that  the  best 
guide  we  could  take  in  the  situation  is  what  businessmen  did  do  when 
they  were  confronted  with  the  kind  of  phenomenon  which  we  are 
now  considering.  That  was  their  reaction  to  the  pressure  of  changes 
in  volume  of  output. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  know  of  cases  where  valuable  machinery 
by  reason  of  some  technological  development  has  become  obsolete 
within  2  or  3  years,  whereas  other  machines  treating  ores  lasted  for 
several  3^ears.  In  the  first  instance,  they  became  obsolete  in  1  or  2 
years,  and  should  have  been  charged  off  during  thai,  year  instead  of 
being  continued  over  several  years. 

Dr.  Yntema.  May  I  read  for  the  committee  one  of  the  introduc- 
tory paragraphs  in  this  statement  by  Mr.  Taitel : 

So  far  as  prices  in  such  an  industry  are  based  upon  costs,  the  pricing  poHcy  would 
tend  to  be  one  that  provides  for  declining  prices  as  volume  of  output  increases. 
Prices  in  the  steel  industry ,  however,  have  not  followed  this  pattern.  They  have 
tended  to  remain  relatively  fixed.  The  typical  practice  has  been  to  increase 
prices  with  increased  volume  rather  than  to  decrease  prices  as  sales  expand.  Such 
price  behavior  is  much  more  consistent  with  the  situation  in  which  increasing 
output  is  associated  with  constant  or  rising  costs. 

That  paragraph,  it  seems  to  me,  abstracts  to  a  considerable  extent 
from  the  factors  which  really  do  account  for  the  cyclical  changes  in 
costs  and  prices.  The  outstanding  characteristics,  which  are  im- 
portant in  determining  the  price  in  the  market,  are  the  tremendous 
shifts  in  demand  in  the  business  cycle.  Those  are  outside  the  control 
of  the  Steel  Corporation  or  the  steel  industry. 

The  second  consideration  which  cannot  be  neglected  is  the  changes 
in  the  prices  which  the  Corporation  and  the  industry  must  pay  for  the 
materials  and  for  the  labor  services  which  they  must  have  for  the 
production  of  their  product.  It  seems  to  me  that  those  have  been 
neglected  i'l  the  particular  suggestion. 

I  should  like  to  call  attention  to  the  chart  which  was  submitted  by 
Mr.  Taitel.  I  do  not  know,  and  I  do  not  think  the  witness  who 
presented  it  knew,  the  basic  material  from  which  it  was  constructed. 
Judging  from  what  I  know  about  the  total  costs  in  the  Corporation, 
and  from  what  I  know  about  the  cost  behavior  in  many  of  the  sub- 
divisions, I  am  inclined  to  be  extremely  skeptical  as  to  the  validity 
of  the  chart,  at  least  mitil  we  know  the  basic  data  upon  which  the 
chart  is  constructed.  I  think  that  we  ought  to  reserve  judgment 
with  respect  to  its  validity. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  didn't  hear  all  the  testimony. 

Dr.  Kreps.  The  chart  is  on  the  easel,  "Exhibit  No.  2184." 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Does  the  chart  indicate  a  fixity  of  price 
for  continued  periods  of  time,  say  for  coal  or  for  ore  or  for  freight 
rates,  notwithstanding  what  we  know  to  be  the  fact  that  has  varied 
very  much  in  price  during  the  past  few  years,  particularly  since  the 


13712       OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Bituminous  Coal  Act,  and  the  price  of  ore  varies,  too,  by  reason  of 
many  conditions 

Dr.  Yntema  (interposing).  Senator,  I  wish  I  knew  the  material 
from  which  this  chart  was  prepared.     I  don't. 

Dr.  Kreps.  You  are  on  the  same  ground  that  we  are  when  we  try 
to  evaluate  your  charts.     Isn't  that  correct? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No;  that  is  not  correct. 

Dr.  Kreps.  We  have  in  no  case  seen  either  the  basic  material  or 
the  work  sheets.  We  know  fully  as  much  about  Mr.  Lippert's  chart  as 
we  know  about  any  of  yours. 

Dr.  Yntema.  But  we  don't  even  know  in  this  case  in  the  chart 
presented  by  Mr.  Taitd  whether  there  has  been  any  adjustment  for 
the  prices  paid  for  the  materials,  any  adjustment  for  wage  rates,  any 
adjustment  for  changes  in  "efficiency.  There  is  no  description  from 
the  material  presented  as  to  what  the  cost  means  from  which  this 
chart  is  derived,  and  I  simply  don't  understand  it,  and  I  don't  see 
how  the  conmiittee  can  possibly  understand  it. 

Acting  Chairman  Ki5ig.  Does  it  assume  ai  sort  of  continuous  line, 
using  the  charts  that  we  have,  for  costs  and  for  those  conditions? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Senator,  I  simply  don't  know;  I  just  don't  know 
what  it  means. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  We  know  that  there  are  constant  variables 
in  so  many  of  the  activities  connected  with  the  steel  industry,  and  for 
that  matter,  all  industries. 

Dr.  LuBiN.  May  I  ask  the  witness:  Dr.  Yntema,  are  you  acquainted 
with  Iron  Age? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes. 

Dr.  LuBiN.  Do  you  accept  it  as  a  reputable  journal? 

Dr.  Yntehja.  What  do  you  mean  by  "reputable"  journal? 

Dr.  LuBiN.  In  the  sense  that  the  members  of  the  industry  quote 
it  as  representing  the  points  of  view  of  conditions  in  the  industry  and 
as  a  good  reporter  of  conditions  in  the  industry. 

Dr.  Yntema.  For  some  statistical  purposes,  I  would  say  it  is  a 
good  reporter.  As  far  as  individual  articles  are  concerned,  especially 
in  a  case  as  technical  as  this,  I  should  say  I  would  want  to  reserve 
judgment  in  appraising  any  particular  article. 

Dr.  Lubin.  Do  you  know  Mr.  Lippert? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  do  not. 

Dr.  Lubin.  Do  you  know  anything  about  his  standing  in  the 
profession? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  do  not. 

Mr.  Lubin.  Do  you  know  whether  members  of  the  Corporation  or 
members  of  the  industry  look  upon  him  as  a  responsible  person? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  do  not. 

Dr.  Lubin.  In  other  words,  then,  when  you  question  his  data,  you 
are  not  questioning  hi^  competency. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Oh,  no,  not  at  all.  I  am  merely  saying  that  I  dont 
know  what  this  means,  and  until  we  have  a  description  of  what  it  is, 
I  suggest  that  we  can't  interpret  it  properly.  He  may  be  completely 
competent.     I  don't  mean  to  imply  he  is  otherwise. 

There  recurs  in  the  statements  by  Mr.  Taitel  as  weU  as  others  the 
implication  that  we  here  have  presented  a  guide  for  pricing  policy 
by  the  Steel  Corporation  and  by  the  steel  industry.  May  I  once  again 
repeat  that  such  is  not  the  case,  that  we  have  attempted  to  present 


CfONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13713 

a  description  of  how  costs  vary  with  output  upon  certain  assump- 
tions. We  have  attempted  to  describe  how  the  volume  of  steel  sold 
by  the  industry  varies  with  the  price  of  steel  to  give  some  basis  for 
judging  what  would  be  the  effects  of  a  change  in  the  price  of  steel 
upon  the  quantity  sold  and  upon  the  profits  and  losses  of  a  corpora- 
tion such  as  the  Steel  Corporation. 

Dr.  Kreps.  The  point  you  are  making  is  very  important.  I  want 
to  underscore  it.  You  emphasize  that  your  analysis  is  "not  a  guide 
for  pricing  policy  by  the  Steel  Corporation  and  by  the  steel  industry." 
It  certainly  is  not  a  guide  for  the  T.  N.  E.  C.  For  example,  let  us 
examine  a  little  more  closely  the  costs  which  you  are  talkmg  about. 
They  do  not  apply  to  any  particular  steel  product?     Correct? 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  costs  apply  to  all  the  steel  products  and  the 
other  operations  of  the  Steel  Corporation. 

Dr.  Keeps.  To  what  you  call  the  "product  mix" 

Dr.  Yntema  (interposing).  The  composite  total  of  aU  products. 

Dr.  Keeps.  They  do  not  apply  to  costs  within  any  particular 
plant. 

Dr.  Yntema.  They  apply  to  costs  within  all  plants. 

Dr.  Keeps.  They  only  apply  to  costs  within  aU  plants  of  the  Steel 
Corporation.  They  do  not  apply  to  costs  within  other  plants  and 
outside  the  Corporation,  nor  to  the  totality  of  such  other  plants  in 
other  corporations,  nor  to  the  steel  industry  as  a  whole. 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  quite  correct;  our  analysis  of  costs  was 
necessarily  restricted-  to  the  material  we  had  in  the  Steel  Corporation^ 

Dr.  Keeps.  In  other  words,  your  cost  curve  is  what  you  regard  a 
convenient  summary  of  cost  experience  as  you  have  seen  it  in  the 
Steel  Corporation  throughout  the  period  which  you  covered. 

Dr.  Yntema.  If  I  may  speak  frankly,  I  don't  like,  the  word  "con- 
venient."    I  would  say  that  io  is  an  inappropriate  description. 

Dr.  Keeps.  I  withdraw  the  word  "convenient."  The  summary  is 
one  that  you  feel  enabled  you  to  get  a  good  glimpse  and  to  give  us  a 
good  glimpse  of  what  seemed  to  you  to  be  the  cost  relationship  for 
those  50,000  products  in  that  varying  product  mix,  composed  of  steel, 
cement,  and  the  like. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Yes,  I  think  that  is  a  correct  statement. 

Dr.  Keeps.  These  are  theoretical  costs,  not  actual  costs. 

Dr.  Yntema,  They  are  actual  costs  adjusted  to  eliminate  the  effect 
of  variables  which  we  did  not  want  to  leave  in  because  they  woiild 
becloud  the  picture. 

Dr.  Keeps.  But  they  are  not  actual  costs  of  any  actual  product. 

Dr.  Yntema.  But  of  the  actual  group  of  all  products. 

Dr.  Keeps.  Nor  are  they  costs  actually  incurred  in  any  actual  plant. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  we  covered  that. 

Dr.  Keeps.  The  distinction  is  extremely  important  and  is  one  upon 
which  there  i&no  disagreement.  I  merely  want  to  help  Dr.  Yntema 
clear  up  the  confusion. 

Dr.  Yntema.  May  I  say  in  concluding  these  remarks  that  I  appre- 
ciate very  much  indeed  the  scientific  character  of  the  discussion  which 
has  just  preceded,  but  that,  in  appraising  it,  I  don't  think  it  alters 
substantially  my  views  as  to  the  applicability  of  our  findings  to  the 
purposes  for  which  they  were  designed. 

Mr.  Fellee.  May  I  just  ask  this  question?  Throughout  this  dis- 
cussion I  have  kept  recurring  in  mv  mind  this  nnestion:  Hero  is  n  vfurv 


13714  OONOENTRATION  OF  BCION  JMIC  POWER 

important  problem  to  be  examined.  Dr.  Yntema  has  examined  it  in 
one-way.  Is  it  possible  to  examine  it  in  another  way?  Dr.  Yntema, 
I  should  like  to  ask  you  from  your  experience  with  the  materials  at 
hand  in  the  Corporation,  would  it  have  been  possible  to  have  dealt 
with  this  problem  of  the  variations  in  costs  at  different  rates  of  output 
by  taking  the  costs  of  a  particular  plant  of  the  Corporation,  and  instead 
of  using  these  historical  aggregate  costs,  to  have  considered  the  costs  of 
the  various  operations  that  go  into  making  steel? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Mr.  Feller,  we  considered  that  with  great  care  before 
we  undertook  our  analysis.  Our  decision  as  to  procedure  was  dictated 
by  these  considerations :  First,  we  were  fearful  if  we  came  to  the  com- 
mittee with  costs  which  involved  necessarily  arbitrary  allocations  of 
overhead  that  we  should  be  criticized  for  any  allocation  that  we  made 
because  any  such  allocation  is  to  some  extent  arbitrary.  In  the  second 
place,  we  thought  the  committee  would  be  more  interested  in  the  total 
picture  than  in  the  picture  presented  in  the  individual  plant.  We  did, 
as  a  matter  of  fact,  make  numerous  studies  of  the  variation  in  costs 
with  output  for  short  periods  of  time  in  individual  plafl.ts,  all  of  which 
confirmed  the  findings  which  we  have  here  presented  with  respect  to 
linearity,  the  straight  line  behavior  of  total  costs  with  volume.  Of 
course,  the  absolute  level  of  those  costs  was  not  material  for  the. 
general  purpose  which  we  had  in  mind. 

I  should  like  to  point  out  also  that  even  if  we  were  to  take  an 
individual  plant  we  would  encounter  the  same  type  of  difficulties  thatQ 
we  encountered  here.  Furthermore,  the  work  would  mount  to  un- 
reasonable proportions  because  each  plant  produces  not  one  product 
but  many  products,  and  for  each  plant,  therefore,  it  would  be  neces- 
sary to  construct  an  index  of  production  to  relate  to  costs,  and  we 
should  have  to  make  all  the  types  of  adjustments  we  have  here.  The 
job  would  be  so  complicated  if  attacked  in  that  way  and  the  results 
would  be  subject  to  such  great  question  that  we  did  not  think'  it 
desirable  to  approach  the  problem  in  that  manner. 

Dr.  LuBiN.  I  should  like  to  ask  Mr.  Yntema  just  a  question  or 
two  in  regard  to  methodology.  Mr.  Yntema,  if  United  States  Steel 
Corporation  would  ask  you  to  appear  and  do  a  job  for  them  on  cost- 
ing, there  are  six  or  seven  products  on  which  there  is  doubt  in  the 
minds  of  certain  officials  as  to  whether  the  price  they  are  charging 
is  the  right  price,  j"ight,  being  the  economic  price,  would  you  proceed 
to  (Jo  the  job  the  way  you  did  this  one  here? 

,  Dr.  Yntema.  The  question  you  are  asking  is  a  very  different  ques- 
tion from  the  one  we  posed,  and  I  should  say  that  consequently  I 
should  approach  it  in  a  different  way.  I  should  go  on  further,  if  I 
may.  Dr.  Lubin,  and  point  out  that  your  question  is  still  an  ambig- 
uous one. 

Dr.  Lubin.  Let's  be  specific.  A  certain  vice  president  "of  a  very 
large  corporation  fcomipented  to  me  recently,  he  doesn't  know  how 
his  prices  are  fixed.  He  was  interested  in  throe  products.  If  he 
asked  you  to  come  in  and  check  up  and  find  out  whether  the  price 
they  are  charging  is  a  proper  economic  price,  particularly  in  view  of 
its  relationship  to  costs,  and  give  thorn  a  cost  picture 

Dr.  Yntema  (interposmg) .  The  proper  economic  price,  according 
to  my  view  of  things,  is  the  price  that  you  can  get  in  the  market. 
It  is  not  determined  in  the  short  run  by  costs;  it  is  determined 
primarily  by  what  your  competitors  will  offer  the  product  for  and 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13715, 

what  the  public  will  pay  for  it.  It  doesn't  seem  to  me  that  in  a 
competitive  situation  the  function  of  costs  in  the  short  run  is  to 
serve  as  a  basis  for  the  establishment  of  price.  That  is  what  I  re- 
ferred to  in  raising  the  issue  with  respect  to  the  interpretation  of 
your  question. 

Dr.  LuBiN.  Let  me  change  my  question  and  be  more  specific.  If 
you  were  asked  by  this  official  to  tell  him  whether  or  not  the  price 
that'  they  are  receiving  is  such  that  it  makes  the  Corporation  a  good 
profit  on  the  basis  of  its  cost,  would  you  proceed  the  way  you  have 
in  this? 

Dr.  Yntema.  No,  because  the  question  is  different  from  the  ques- 
tion W  which  we  addressed  ourselves.  We  were  not  concerned  in 
this  particular  problem  with  the  individual  product  prices,  the 
reasons  for  that  I  have  tried  to  point  out.  If  it  had  been  possible 
to  present  unambiguous  results,  and  the  burden  of  expense  and  time 
had  not  been  toe  great,  we  should  have  been  only  too  glad  to  attack 
that  problem,  but  we  worked  (a)  under  limitations  of  time  and  ex- 
pense, and  (6)  also  under  limitations  that  are  theoretically  inherent 
in  the  problem,  that  is,  with  reference  to  the  allocation  of  overhead 
or  fixed  costs. 

Dr.  LuBiN.  In  other  words,  frankly,  my  purpose  in  asking  this,  I 
am  trying  to  formulate  in  my  own  mind  what  these  figures  are  good 
for. 

Dr.  Yntema.  These  figures  are  good,  if  I  may  say  it  again,  for 
these  purposes;  we  wanted  to  find  out  on  the  demand  side  how  the 
total  quantity  of  steel  sold  would  vary  with  the  price.  You  might 
approach  that  product  by  product.  I  think  you  would  get  into 
difficulties  which  would  make  your  problem  insoluble  if  you  did  so, 
because  of  the  substitutability  among  products.  In  the  second  place, 
we  wanted  to  find  out  how  the  costs  in  a  concern  such  as  the  Steel 
Corporation  varied  with  output  to  discover  what  would  be  the  effects 
of  price  reductions  or  price  increases  upon  the  costs  of  such  a  corpora- 
tion.    We  merely  want  to  present  such  information  to  the  committee. 

Dr.  LuBiN.  In  doing  that  latter,  you  had  to  use  certain  arbitrary 
assumptions. 

Dr.  Yntema.  It  depends  upon  what  you  mean  by  "arbitrary 
assumptions." 

Dr.  LuBiN.  You  had  to  make  a  decision.  Shall  we  allocate  this  way, 
or  that  way? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  just  what  we  didn't  do  for  the  most  part. 
We  attempted  to  select  a  method  which  would  minimize  the  necessity 
of  arbitrary  allocation.  That  is  why  we  did  what  we  did;  we  didn't 
want  to  engage  in  any  more  arbitrary  allocation  than  was  necessary. 

Dr.  LuBiN.  Wasn't  selection  of  the  method  itself  an  arbitrary 
thing?     You  might  have  selected  another  method. 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  quite  right,  but  the  selection  of  the  method 
is  arbitrary  only  insofar  as  there  is  a  set  of  alternatives  for  the  pur- 
pose you  have  in  mind. 

Dr.  LuBiN.  What  I  am  trying  to  get  to.  is  whether  or  not  Mr. 
Feller  hasn't  really  struck  the  kernel  of  things,  that  the  same  job 
might  have  been  done  by  somebody  equally  well  with  a  different  set 
of  assumptions  and  different  set  of  methods  and  gotten  entirely 
different  results,  and  although  you  might  not  have  agreed,  there 
might  have  been  people  wiio  did,  in  fact  you  might  have  found  two 


13716       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

corporations  doing  this  thing  differently,  getting  different  results,  and 
both  having  authority  for  their  methods. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  see  what  you  are  driving  at,  I  think.  Let  me  say 
this  in  answer  to  it:  I  think  it  is  possible,  given  sufficient  time  and 
money  and  patience,  to  study  the  relationship  of  the  costs  which  are 
associated  directly  with  individual  plants  in  relation  to  their  output. 
The  problem  is  an  overwhelmingly  great  one  if  you  are  going  to  cover 
any  considerable  territory,  and  it  still  leaves  untouched  a  certain 
important  realm,  that  is,  namely,  the  allocation  of  the  overhead  not 
associated  with  those  individual  plants.  To  some  extent  you  can  get 
part  way  in  the  problem,  but  there  still  is  a  margin  of  indeterminancy 
in  any  solution  that  you  obtain  by  it. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  That  becomes  more  of  a  problem  if  you 
have  several  hundred  or  several  thousand  commodities  growing  out 
of  this  same  general  activity. 

Dr.  Yntema.  You  would  have  the  same  problem,  plant  by  plant, 
as  you  have  in  deahng  with  the  total  corporation. 

Dr.  LuBiN.  I  had  an  old  professor  on'^e  you  probably  know  him, 
Henry  Carter  Adams,  a  man  who  institute  .  the  first  series  of  accounts 
for  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission.  The  first  sentence  he 
always  told  us  in  his  classes  was  that  accounting  was  purposive ;  your 
purpose  would  determine  the  method  you  used.  I  wonder  whether 
the  same  wouldn't  be  appUcable  to  the  testimony  you  have  presented. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  that  is  a  very  important  question  which  you 
have  raised.  We  selected  this  method  on  the  basis  of  two  considera- 
tions, its  applicability  of  method  and  the  exigencies  of  time  and 
expense.  And  I  should  like  to  point  this  out,  if  I  may:  That  neither 
ordinary  accounting  records  nor  cost-accounting  records  reveal 
immediately  the  kind  of  data  which  we  needed,  and  that  is  why  we 
resorted  to  this  type  of  analysis  which  we  think  is  applicable  to  the 
problem  for  which  we  designed  it. 

Mr.  Feller.  I  should  like  to  ask  you  another  question  along  this 
line.  As  I  understand  the  method  used,  the  fundamental,  the  basic 
datum  in  the  whole  tiling  is  a  chart,  a  scatter  diagram,  as  statisticians 
call  it,  on  which  you  place  12  dots.  It  all  began  from  that,  didn't  it, 
the  cost- volume  relationship  in  each  of  12  years? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  think  there  is  some  misapprehension  on  the  part  of 
those  who  havf^  participated  in  the  discussion  as  to  the  relative  import- 
ance of  the  demand  side  and  the  cost  side.  I  should  say  that  the 
inelasticity  of  the  demand  for  steel  is  important  as  well  as  the  cost 
behavior.  I  should  deny  that  it  all  started  in  this  one  httle  scatter 
diagram. 

Mr.  Feller.  I  agree  with  you  and  I  would,  like  to  amend  that.  I 
was  addressing  my  remarks  entirely  to  the  cost  analysis.  I  may  say 
that  my  question  might  be  quite  different  if  I  were  addressing  myself 
to  the  demand.  Just  to  narrow  dowTi  my  question,  have  you  tried, 
or  is  it  possible  to  try,  to  put  more  dots  on  by  taking  more  years? 
In  other  words,  supposing  you  went  back  to  1906  and  plotted  that, 
have  you  tried  checking  your  results  by  taking  more  years? 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  reason  for  the  selection  of  the  years  which  we 
took  was  that  we  did  not  have  satisfactory  records  for  the  t.djustment 
of  the  pay  rolls  for  prior  years.  I  don't  want  the  impression  to  remain 
that  the  evidence  in  the  chart  is  the  only  evidence  on  \Nnich  we  based 
our  final  conclusions.     We  confirmed  this  study,  as  I  said,  by  numerous 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13717 

other  studies,  and  speaking  now  as  a  statistician  and  economist,  I 
was  amazed  to  find  how  closel;^  in  so  many  cases  the  total  costs  were 
almost  precisely  a  linear  function  of  output.  It  was  one  of  the  real 
surprises  of  my  life  as  an  economist. 

Mr.  Feller.  Was  it  possible  to  test  the  result,  that  is,  the  linear 
result,  by  analyzing  the  profit-and-loss  record  of  the  Corporation? 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  don't  think  that  would  give  nearly  as  satisfactory 
results  as  this.  If  you  take  the  profit  or  loss  record,  the  profits  or 
losses  are  a  function  both  of  the  prices  charged  and  the  costs  which 
are  involved,  and  it  does  not  seem  to  me  that  tnat  is  an  appropriate 
type  of  analysis. 

Mr.  Feller.  I  would  like  to  put  it  to  you  concretely.  Supposing 
you  took  the  records  of  operation  of  the  Corpojation  from  July  1938 
to  January  1940 — now,  that  is  a  period  that  covers  six  quarters — in 
which  there  has  been  no  substantial  price  change,  wouldn't  that  be  a 
good  test  period,  not  necessarily  to  derive  a  fine  like  this,  but  to  test 
whether  or  not  the  line  that  you  have  derived  is  an  accurate  one? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Well,  there  are  difficulties  in  that.  For  one  thing, 
you  will  run  into  some  problems  in  connection  with  seasonal  varia- 
tions of  cost.  There  is  one  difficulty  iji  connection  with  t^at  that  is 
rather  serious. 

We  did  test  out  our  material  by  studying  the  variation  of  pay  roUs 
and  of  hours  worked  with  output,  and  got  confirmation  of  our  findings. 
I  should  be  rather  skeptical  of  the  sort  of  procedure  you  suggest,  and 
again  I  want  to  make  clear  that  we  did  not  have  all  the  time  in  the 
world  to  undertake  the  study.     We  were  limited. 

We  were  engaged  in  a  large  number  of  other  studies  besides  this  one, 
and  we  made  the  best  of  what  facilities  we  had.  I  doubt  very  much 
that  the  profit-and-loss  analysis  you  suggest  would  throw  great  light, 
however,  on  the  problem 

Mr.  Wooden.  Might  I  ask  a  question?  Dr.  Yntema,  can  you  say 
whether  the  average  price  level  in  1939  was  less  than  in  1938? 

Dr.  Yntema.  May  I  answer  that  with  a  chart?  I  think  I  can 
show  that  very  easily. 

Mr.  Wooden.  I  mean  for  steel. 

Dr.  Yntema.  May  I  show  you  that  by  chart? 

Mr.  Wooden.  Any  way  you  like. 

Dr.  Yntema.  Let  me  present  this  chart,  if  I  may.  This  chart  is 
numbered  C-9,  "Exhibit  No.  1409."  It  is  entitled,  "Reported  Com- 
posite Price  and  Composite  MUl  Net  Yield."  ^  The  heavy  line  in 
the  chart  represents  an  index  of  the  composite  mill  net  yield  to  the 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries.  The  dotted  line  is  the 
reported  composite  price  by  "Iron  Age."  This  line  extends  in  1939 
through  November,  and  it  is  apparently  from  inspection  of  the  chart 
that  the  average  price  reported  by  "Iron  Age"  is  substantially  lower  in 
1939  than  in  1938,  and  also  that  the  composite  mill  net  yield  to  the 
Corporation  is  similarly  substantially  lower  in  1939. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Is  it  as  much  as  10  percent  lower? 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  reduction  from  the  high  point  in  1938  to  the 
low  point  m  1939  is  from  105.9  for  the  mill  net  yield  to  91.4  That 
would  be  a  drop  of  14.5  points,  a  drop  of  approximately  14  percent 
from  the  high  point  in  1938. 

« Appendix,  p.  13815. 


13718       CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Mr.  Wooden.  On  page  16  of  your  prepared  statement  which  you 
read,  you  estimated  that  a  10  percent  decrease  from  the  1938  average 
level  would  produce  only  11  percent  increase  in  volume. 

Dr.  Yntema.  No,  we  didn't  estimate  that.  What  we  said  was  that 
was  more  than  the  most  optimistic  response  which  could  be  expected. 
We  didn't  mean  to  imply  that  we  thought  that  was  a  reasonable 
expectation. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Was  that  more  than  could  be  expected? 

Dr.  YNTEkA.  Oh,  yes.  Our  best  guess  is  that  the  elasticity  of  de- 
mand was  probably  not  more  than  0.3  or  0.4,  that  a  10-percent  reduc- 
tion in  price  probably  wouldn't  of  itself  bring  about  more  than  perhaps 
a  3  or  4  percent  increase  in  volume.  That  was  a  very  crude  estimate ; 
it  may  be  more  than  that,  or  less  than  that. 

Mr.  Wooden.  Is  that  consistent  with  the  fact  that  during  1939  the 
total  volume  for  the  industry  iiicreased  as  much  as  65  percent? 

Dr.  Yntema.  Our  statement  is  not  at  all  inconsistent  with  the  facts. 
We  went  to  considerable  length  to  point  out  that  the  primary  factors 
determining  the  quantity  of  steel  sold,  are  industrial  profits,  national 
income,  or,  if  you  want  to  put  it  in  another  form,  other  industrial 
activity,  and  that  the  price  is  a  relatively  minor  factor.  I  should  say 
that  the  evidence  for  the  years  which  you  cite  bears  out  exactly  the 
findings  which  we  have  submitted  to  the  committee,  that  there  were 
other  factors  far  more  important  than  price  which  determined  the 
course  of  events  in  those  years. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Any  other  questions? 

Dr.  Lubin.  Is  it  possible  to  find  out  how  much  these  other  factors 
weigh  as  opposed  to  price  changes? 

Dr.  Yntema.  That  is  a  far-reaching  question,  Dr.  Lubin,  and  a 
very  good  one.  One  of  the  devices  open  to  us  is  to  attempt  a  multiple 
correlation  analysis.  The  results  of  such  analysis  have  been  taken 
somewhat  more  seriously  by  the  committee  than  I  thought  they  would 
be  taken.  I  should  regard  the  results  of  our  correlation  analysis  as 
merely  confirmatory  of  our  other  findings,  and  I  should  not  attach 
great  precision  to  the  results  which  are  obtained  thereby.  I  think 
they  do,  however,  give  us  some  evidence  on  a  very  complicated,  diffi- 
cult problem. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Thank  you  very  much.  Doctor. 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  suggest  that  Mr.  Taitel  be  di-:  /-^ed  as  a  witness. 
Dr.  Yntema  will  probably  wish  to  make  comments  later  on. 

Dr.  Yntema.  I  should  like  to  respond  to  several  of  the  points  which 
Dr.  Ezekiel  raised  in  his  testimony 

Dr.  Kreps.  That  may  be  done  tomorrow. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  The  committee  will  stand  adjourned  until 
10:30. 

Dr.  Kreps.  I  should  like  to  add  a  word  of  thanks  to  Dr.  Yntema, 
who  consented  while  the  material  is  still  fresh  in  our  minds,  to  stay 
with  us  and  give  us  the  benefit  of  his  additional  comments. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  think  we  are  indebted  to  him. 

(WTiereupon,  at  4:45  p.  m.,  the  committee  recessed  until  10:30  a.  m., 
Thursday,  January  25,  1940.) 


INVESTIGATION  OF  CONCENTKATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


THURSDAY,  JANUARY  25,  1940 

United  States  Senate, 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee, 

Washington,  D.  C. 

The  committee  met  at  10:45  a.  m.,  pursuant  to  adjournment  on 
Wednesday,  January  24,  1940,  in  the  Caucus  Room,  Senate  Office 
Building,  Joseph  J.  O'Connell,  Jr.,  special  assistant  to  the  General 
Counsel,  Trfe    ary  Department,  presiding. 

Present:  Mr.  O'Connell  (acting  chairman),  Senator  King,  Repre- 
sentative Wilhams. 

Present  also:  John  V.  W.  Reynders,  representing  the  Department 
of  Commerce;  Walter  B.  Wooden,  representing  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission;  Frank  P.  Smith,  representing  the  Securities  and  Ex- 
change Commission;  Martin  Taitel,  senior  consulting  economist. 
Work  Projects  Administration;  A.  H.  Feller,  special  assistant  to  the 
Attorney  General,  and  Melvin  G.  deChazeau,  consulting  economist, 
Department  of  Justice. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  The  committee  will  please  be  in 
order. 

Dr.  Kreps  being  ill  today,  Mr.  Feller  is  going  to  take  his  place. 
Will  you  introduce  the  first  witness,  Mr.  Feller? 

Mr.  Feller.  Mr.  Chairman,  I  imagine  that  my  ignorance  of  the 
science  of  econometrics  is  almost  unparalleled,  and  I  may  be  in  con- 
siderable difficulty  in  conducting  examination  of  this  very  abstruse 
science. 

Yesterday  afternoon,  the  committee  may  remember,  Dr.  Yntema 
pointed  out  that  his  analysis  had  two  parts  of  great  significance. 
One  part  was  the  analysis  of  cost  and  the  other  was  the  analysis  of 
demand.  The  testimony  yesterday  was  Concerned  mainly  with  the 
analysis  of  the  cost  situation  by  Dr.  Yntema.  I  should  like  to  call  to 
the  stand  Dr.  Louis  H.  Bean,  who,  I  understand,  will  discuss  the  other 
problem,  the  problem  of  demand. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell. -Will  you  hold  up  your  right  hand, 
Dr.  Bean,  please.  Do  you  solemnly  swear  that  the  testimony  you 
are  about  to  give  in  this  proceeding  will  be  the  truth,  the. whole  truth, 
and  nothing  but  the  truth,  so  help  you  God? 

Dr.  Bean.  I  do. 

TESTIMONY   OF  DR.   LOUIS   BEAN,   ECONOMIC   ADVISER. 
DEPARTMENT  OF  AGRICULTURE,  WASHINGTON,  D.  C. 

Mr.  Feller.  Dr.  Bean,  will  you  state  your  name  and  position  for 
the  reporter? 

Dr.  Bean.  Louis  H.  Bean,  economist  in  the  Bureau  of  Agricultural 
Economics  of  the  Department  of  Agriculture. 

13719 


13720  OONOENTIIATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Mr.  Feller.  How  long  have  you  been  with  the  Department  of 
Agriculture? 

Dr.  Bean.  I  have  been  with  the  Department  of  Agriculture  16 
years. 

Mr.  Feller.  And  you  are  primarily  a  statistician? 

Dr.  Bean.  I  am  primarily  an  economist,  doing  a  great  deal  of 
statistical  work. 

Mr.  Feller.  Where  did  you  receive  your  training  as  statistical 
economist? 

Dr.  Bean.  I  am  a  graduate  of  the  University  of  Rochester,  Roch- 
ester, N.  Y.,  and  Harvard  School  of  Business;  sinee  graduating  from 
the  Harvard  School  of  Business,  I  have  been  with  the  Bureau  of 
Agricultural  Economics. 

Mr.  Feller.  Do  you  have  a  statement,  Dr.  B;ean? 

Dr.  Bean.  I  have  a  statenaent. 

Mr.  Feller.  Will  you  proceed? 

EXAMINATION   OF   UNITED   STATES   STEEL   CORPORATION  ANALYSES 

Dr.  Bean.  An  examination  of  the  four  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 
statements  on  demand  analyses  for  steel  in  the  container,  automobile 
and  railroad  industries  and  for  all  industries  combined,  reveals  grave 
statistical  defects.  These  are  defects  in  methods  of  analysis  as  well 
as  in  assumptions  and  in  data.  In  the  first  three  of  these  studies,  the 
important  objective  was  to  reveal  the  effect  of  price  on  consumption, 
but  the  methods  and  data  used  were  inadequate,  with  the  result  that 
the  quantitative  conclusions  arrived  at  are  unreliable,  and  so  gen- 
erally recognized  by  the  authors.  In  some  cases  adequate  data  were 
not  fully  utilized  and  important  price-volume  relationships  remained 
undetected. 

In  the  study  dealing  with  total  steel  consumption  by  ail  industries, 
several  of  the  quantitative  analyses  presented  are  statistically  im- 
reliable  because  of  the  wide  range  within  which  the  "true"  relation- 
ships between  price  and  volume  may  lie.  No  account  was  taken  of 
the  extent  to  which  one  or  two  extreme  observations  influenced  the 
results  obtained.  In  certain  cases  where  the  analyses  show  little 
influence  of  price  on  volume,  a  close  examination  of  the  data  used 
reveals  substantial  price  influence ;  and  in  cases  where  low  prices  were 
found  to  be  associated  with  low  volume,  the  underlying  relationships 
can  be  shown  to  be  just  the  opposite. 

The  conclusion  of  the  analysis  of  the  demand  for  steel  in  the  auto- 
mobile industry  is  that  the  elasticity  of  the  demand  for  steel  used  as  a 
raw  material  in  the  automobile  industry  is  very  low,  and  that  a  10- 
percent  reduction  in  the  price  of  automotive  steel  would  increase  car 
sales  by  only  1%  percent  and  the  consumption  of  automotive  steel 
by  not  more  than  2  or  3  percent. 

In  support  of  this  conclusion,  there  is  presented  on  page  19  a  scatter 
diagram  purporting  to  show  the  relation  of  automotive  steel  prices  to 
total  automobile  steel  consumption  for  the  years  1924-38.  It  is 
claimed  that  this  scatter  diagimn  of  percentage  changes  in  the  annual 
consumption  and  annual  average  price  "fails  to  indicate  that  lower 
steel  prices  aro  associated  with  greater  quantities  of  steel  purchased 
and  vice  versa."  Actually,  the  basic  relationship  does  indicate  that 
lower  steel  prices  are  associated  with  increased  consumption  of  steel 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13721 

in  automobile  production.  The  failure  of  the  authors  to  note  this  is 
due  to  the  fact  that  there  are  other  factors  besides  the  price  of  steel 
which  cause  changes  in  the  total  consumption  of  steel  in  automobiles 
and  that  statistically  it  is  not  possible  to  determine  the  effect  of  one 
factor  on  another  when  the  other  important  elements  in  the  problem 
are  not  taken  into  account. 

(Senator  King  assumed  the  Chair.) 

Acting  Chairman  King.  General  improvement  in  conditions  would 
necessarily  increase  the  production  and  sale  of  automobiles,  without 
much  regard  for  the  price  of  steel. 

Dr.  Bean.  If  that  factor  is  not  taken  into  account,  Senator,  then 
the  underlying  effect  of  price  on  volume  cannot  be  clearly  seen. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  There  are  so  many  factors  that  must  be 
taken  into  account  in  determining  the  question  of  costs,  cost  prices. 

Dr.  Bean.  That  I  take  it  was  gone  into  quite  thoroughly  yesterday. 
In  a  moment,  Senator,  I  think  I  shall  be  able  to  indicate  to  you  how 
it  is  possible  to  take  this  factor  of  demand  into  account  in  this  partic- 
ular illustration. 

Had  the  authors  of  this  analysis  taken  into  account  changes  in  the 
level  of  demand,  they  would  have  found  an  inverse  relation  between 
the  price  of  automotive  steel  and  automobile  steel  consumption. 
Even  in  the  scatter  diagram  on  page  19  it  is  clear  that  the  relation  of 
price  to  consumption  is  negative,  as  is  indicated  by  the  observations 
for  the  years  1925  to  1929,  inclusive.  Similarly,  the  observations  for 
the  years  1930-32  and  1933-37  show  the  inverse  relationships  but  at 
different  levels  of  demand. 

May  I  take  a  moment  to  illustrate  what  these  words  mean.  The 
chart  on  page  19- 

Mr.  Feller  (interposing).  Page  19  of  "Exhibit  No.  1413,"  ^  entitled 
"Analysis  of  the  Demand  for  Steel  in  the  Automobile  Industry." 

Dr.  Bean.  This  is  an  enlargement  of  that  chart. 

Now,  the  reason  I  call  your  attention  to  it  is  that  it  is  used  as  a  sort 
of  clincher  to  the  aigument  that  price  is  relatively  unimportant,  and 
that  as  far  as  this  illustration  is  concerned,  it  does  not  show  that  lower 
prices  are  associated  with  increased,  consumption. 

I  have  already  pointed  out  that  in  certain  years,  there  is  an  inverse 
relationship.  If  you  examine  the  data  for. the  years  1925,  1926,  1927, 
1928,  and  1929  only,  you  find  that  the  relation  of  price  change  to 
volume  change  is  negative;  that  is,  reductions  in  volume  being  asso- 
ciated with  price  advances.  If  you  take  another  group  of  years  in 
sequence,  1933,  1934,  1935,  1936,  and  1937,  these  observations  also 
lie  along  a,  negatively  sloped  regression.  Similarly,  if  you  take  the 
price  decline  in  years  of  business  depression,  namely,  1930,  1931,  1932, 
and  1938,  you  also  have  a  suggestion  that  the  relationship  is  negative. 
I  want  to  come  back  to  this  illustration  in  another  moment. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Doctor,  have  you  taken  into  account  in 
your  study  the,  what  shall  I  say,  psychological  condition  of  the  people 
resulting  from  apprehensions  of  bad  or  good  legislation,  bad  or  good 
times,  foreign  affairs,  possibility  of  protracted  peace  or.  of  a  violent 
war;  are  not  all  of  those  things  to  be  taken  into  account  when  you  are 
trying  to  formulate  a  rule,  if  you  can  call  it  a  rule,  for  the  determina- 
tion of  the  cause  of  the  rise  or  decline  in  prices? 

'  Appendix  p .  13993. 


13722     oonoeNtration  of  economic  power 

Dr.  Bean.  Your  question,  Senator,  leads  me  to  think  that  I  ought  to 
make  clear  the  position  in  which  I  appear  here  as  a  witness.  I  have 
not  undertaken  to  analyze  the  supply  and  demand  factors  for  the 
steel  industry.  I  have  spent  a  great  deal  of  time  over  these  reports 
that  have  been  submitted  to  you.'  They  are  the  kinds  of  studies  for 
which  many  of  us  statisticians  and  economists  have  been  waiting  for 
years.  They  contain  a  great  deal  of  very  useful  and  interesting 
information.  Having  studied  factors  which  affect  agricultural  and 
industrial  prices,  I  have  looked  at  these  reports  quite  minutely  to 
glean  from  them  fundamental  knowledge  about  the  iron  and  steel 
industry.  I  am  here  merely  to  pass  on  to  you,  who.  undoubtedly  have 
not  examined  these  things  in  as  close  detail  as  I  have,  some  of  the 
over-all  impressions  that,  as  a  statistician,  I  obtained  from  studying 
these  reports.  I  have  no  original,  contribution  to  make  except, 
perhaps,  to  indicate  to  you'  the  method  by  which  I  examined  these 
statistical  reports. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Of  course,  you  woidd  concede  that  the 
situation  in  Asia,  where  Japan  has  obtained  for  a  number  of  years 
large  quantities  of  scrap  and  steel,  would  affect  the  prices  more  or  less, 
or  affect  the  market  or  the  demand  for  steel? 
JDr.  Bean.  I  would,  yes. 

Acting  Chan-man  King.  And  similarly,  conditions  in  Europe,  if  we 
have  peace  or  war? 

Dr.  Bean.  I  think  so  le  of  these  unusual  conditions  show  up 
suggestively  in  some  of  t!  e  material  that  I  want  to  go  over  with  you. 
By  introducing  the  additional  factor  of  changes  in  industrial  pro- 
duction (as  a  measure  of  changes  in  the  level  of  demand)  into  this 
analysis,  it  can  be  shown  that  for,  a  given  reduction  in  automobile 
prices,  the  associated  increases  in  automobile-steel  consumption  have 
varied  directly  with  the  rate  of  change  in  business. 

When  changes  in  industrial  production  are  inircduced  in  this 
analysis,  we  find  that  the  price  changes  in  the  years  1933,  1935  and 
1936  are  associated  with  increases  in  industrial  production  of  14  to 
19  percent. 

Price  changes  in  the  years  1925,  1926,  1928,  and  1929  with  increases 
in  industrial  production  of  4  to  10  percent;  in  the  years  1927  and  1924 
with  decreases  in  industrial  production  of  2  and  6  percent  respectively; 
and  in  the  years  1930,  1931,  1932,  and  1938  with  decreases  of  16  to 
22  percent  in  industrial  activity.  The  only  2  years  for  which  the  data 
seems  to  be  out  of  line  are  1934  and  1937  when  factors  other  than  the 
relatively  small  changes  in  industrial  production  apparently  supported 
automobile-steel  consumption  at  a  relatively  higher  level.  If  bookings 
instead  of  the  indirect  measure  of  consumption  used  here  were  avail- 
able, it  is  quite  likely  that  these  2  years  (1934  and  1937)  would  also 
show  as  consistent  a  relation  of  price  to  volume  as  we  find  for  all  the 
other  years  in  this  analysis. 

,In  other  words,  in  this  chart  ^  that  I  have  just  described  there  are 
15  observations,  13  of  those  15  lie  in  such  a  position  as  to  indicate  an 
inverse  relation  of  price  to  volume,  and  the  2  exceptional  years, 
were  undoubtedly  years  of  greater  anticipations,  speculation  in  indus- 
try, that  distort  the  price  volume  relationship. 

'  Exhibits  introduced  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation. 
'  Chart  6  of  '.'Exhibit  No.  1413";  appendix,  p.  13993. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13723 

Mr.  O'CoNNELL.  You  mean  a  decrease  in  prices  associated  with 
substantial  increases  in  demand  in  those  years. 

Dr.  Bean.  May  I  illustrate  by  referrmg  to  chart  6  of  "Exhibit 
No.  1413." » 

I  would  like  to  take  years  when  business  was  rising  rapidly,  some- 
where between  15  and  19  percent  per  year.  There  are  three  cases 
of  that  sort  in  this  analysis.  They  are  these  years  right  here,  1933,  35, 
and  '36,  and  I  think  any  of  you  dealing  with  just  those  3  years  would 
observe  that  the  relation  of  these  three  points  is  such  as  to  indicate  a 
.  negative  relationship  at  this  level  of  demand.  These  other  years 
when  business  was  rising  rapidly  are  here.  Let's  now  take  years 
when  business  was  rising  moderately,  somewhere  between  4  and  10 
percent  a  year,  instead  of  15  to  19.  The  years  of  that  type  are  1925, 
'28,  '26,  and  2  additional  years,  '34  ajid  '37. 

There  is  another  type  of  situation,  namely,  when  business  is  declin- 
ing rapidly,  as  in  the  years  1930,  '31,  '32,  and  '38,  and  the  underlying 
relationship  here  too  is  a  negative  one.  These  data  show  that  the 
underlying  relationship  of  price  changes  to  volume  changes  is  negative, 
if  the  different  business  situations  are  taken  into  account.  This 
illustration  is  not  conclusive  evidence  that  price  changes  and  volume 
changes  do  not  reveal  a  negative  relationship. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  You  appreciate,  I  suppose,  Doctor,  that 
the  introduction  into  our  stream  of  economic  business  life,  a  very 
large  Federal  contribution,  such  as  2  or  3  billion  of  dollars  duriag  the 
bonus  period,  and  the  large  appropriation  of  more  than  $3,600,000,000 
just  for  relief  and  other  matters  in  193^3,  would  necessarily  have  some 
effect  upon  business  and  upon  prices,  it  would  revive  in  some  instances 
and  possibly  result  in  a  decline  in  other  avenues  of  business  activity. 

Dr.  Bean.  But  none  of  these  things.  Senator,  alter  the  basic  fact, 
if  it  is  a  fact,  as  revealed  here  that  the  relation  between  price  and 
volume  is  basically  inverse.  That  relationship  may  be  hidden  com- 
pletely by  the  things  that  you  have  mentioned,  but  the  underlying 
fact  of  an  inverse  relation  between  price  and  volume  isn't  altered. 
The  things  you  mention  may  swamp  that  basic  relationship,  if  we 
may  put  it  that  way,  or  cancel  it;  but  price  nevertheless  has  its  basic 
influence  and  my  point  is  merely  that  there  is  an  inverse  relationship 
between  price  and  volume  that  can  be  revealed  by  the  very  materials 
which  in  this  report  it  is  claimed  do  not  reveal  it. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  Well,  prices  are  affected  by  the  volume  of 
currency  and  the  credit  extended  with  the  banks.     Isn't  that  true? 

Dr.  Bean.  Yes. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  And,  of  course,  business  then  reacts  to 
those  changes  which  result  from  the  condition  just  alluded  to. 

Dr.  Bean.  That  is  quite  true.  We  are,  however,  talking  about  a 
report,  Senator,  which  purports  to  portray  the  relation  of  price  to 
volume  with  all  of  these  other  things  held  constant  or  held  unchanged. 

Acting  Chairman  King.  I  am  not  talking  about  that  report  because 
some  of  these  reports  and  some  of  the  addresses  of  learned  doctors 
and  statisticians  may  not  always  afford  a  true  basis  for  conclusions 
which  may  be  reached  with  respect  to  causes  and  effects  in  the  rise  and 
fall  of  prices  and  in  expansion  and  recession  of  business. 

1  Appendix,  p.  13393 . 

124491 — 41— pt.  26 10 


13724  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Mr.  Feller.  Dr.  Bean,  would  it  be  correct  to  say  that  your  testi- 
mony is  directed  to  precisely  the  point  that  the  Senator  has  just 
raised?  In  other  words,  does  analysis  and  demand  presented  on  behalf 
of  the  Corporation  reveal  a  true  picture  of  the  relationship  between 
price  and  demand? 

Dr.  Bean.  As  far  as  this  particular  illustration  is  concerned,  it  does 
not  to  me.  The  statement  is  made  in  the  report  ^  that  this  analysis 
does  not  reveal  an  inverse  relation  of  volume  and  price.  By  making  a 
simple  refinement  in  that  analysis,  I  do  find  an  inverse  relationship. 

The  mere  introduction  of  this  additional  factor  representing  changes 
in  the  level  of  demand  not  only  gives  clear  indication  of  a  negative 
relationship  of  price  and  volume  but  greatly  clarifies  the  interacting 
and  at  times  the  counteracting  influences  of  price  changes  and  demand 
changes  on  the  changes  in  the  volume  of  automobile  steel  consump- 
tion. Thus  for  a  10  percent  reduction  in  automobile  steel  prices,  the 
associated  increase  in  automobile  steel  consumption  was  about  80 
percent  when  business  activity  was  increasing  at  a  rate  of  about 
15  percent  per  year.  It  was  about  50  percent  when  business  activity 
was  increasing  at  a  rate  of  5  to  10  percent  per  year,  and  about  20  to  30 
percent  with  business  conditions  remaining  unchanged.  On  the 
other  hand,  with  business  activity  falhng  around  20  percent  per  year, 
a  10  percent  reduction  in  automobile  steel  prices  was  accompanied 
by  a  reduction  in  automobile  steel  consumption  of  about  30  percent. 

These  relationships  are  not  to  be  taken  as  final  but  merely  as  an 
indication  that  the  general  conclusion  contained  in  the  analysis  of 
demand  for  automobile  steel  of  a  0.2  to  0.3  elasticity  of  demand  under 
normal  conditions  appears  to  be  a  substantial  understatement. 

The  effect  of  price  on  the  amount  of  steel  used  per  car  appears  to  be 
understated  in  this  analysis.  This  may  be  judged  by  comparing  the 
price  of  automotive  steel  (given  in  table  10  of  "Exhibit  No.  1413"^  with 
the  amount  of  steel  consumed  per  motor  vehicle.  ^  There  is  here  an  un- 
mistakable inverse  relationship  between  the  price  of  steel  and  the 
amount  of  steel  per  car. 

For  example,  in  1924  the  price  of  automotive  steel  is  given  as  3.45 
cents,  the  amount  of  steel  consumed  per  motor  vehicle  is  given  as  ap- 
proximately 0.8  of  a  ton.  By  1928  the  price  ot  automotive  steel  had 
been  reduced  to  2.67  cents  and  the  amount  of  steel  per  motor  vehicle 
had  increased  to  1.4  tons.  Similarly,  for  the  period  1929  to  1933  we 
find  the  price  in  1929  of  2.69  cents  associated  with  steel  consumed  per 
vehicle  of  1.16  tons;  and  the  lower  price  of  steel  in  1933  of  1.89  cents 
associated  with  steel  consumed  per  vehicle  of  1.8  tons.  Conversely, 
the  higher  prices  for  steel  in  1934-38  are  associated  with  smaller 
steel  consumption  per  car,  averaging  about  1.4  tons. 

The  exact  relationship  between  the  price  of  automotive  steel  and  the 
consumption  of  steel  per  vehicle  is  difficult  to  determine.  For  the 
period  of  the  1920's  the  gross  relation  between  price  and  consumption 
of  steel  per  vehicle  suggests  an  elasticity  of  2  or  more.  For  the  period 
1933  to  1936  the  gross  relation  between  price  and  volume  of  steel  per 
vehicle  suggests  an  elasticity  of  1.  For  the  entire  period  1924  to  1938 
the  over-all  relation  suggests  an  average  elasticity  of  somewhat  less 
than  1.  These  figures  are  greatly  at  variance  with  the  conclusion  of 
the  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  analysis  that  "price  considerations  have  a 

1  "Exhibit  No.  1413". 
>  Aiipendix,  p.  13997. 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13725 

minor  influence  in  determining  the  consumption  of  automobile  steel" 
and  that  the  elasticity  of  demand  fdr  steel  as  a  raw  material  in  the 
automobile  industry  is  probably  no  higher  than  0.2  or  0.3. 

Mr.  Feller.  May  I  jilst  ask  you  a  question  there?  The -relation- 
ship which  you  have  pointed  out  between  the,' price  6f  steel  and  the 
amount. of  steel  used  per  car  is  a  relationship,  as  I^ understand  it, 
which  is  derived  from  observation  of  the  historical  data,  and  it  does 
not  necessarily  suggest,  does  it,  that  the  changes  in  the  amount  of  steel 
per  car  were  due  entirely  to  the  price  factor;  i^^  ther  words,  they 
may  have  been  due  to  technical  factors  ^nd  to  ne  .styling  and  to  !new 
technological  equipment  which  made  it  possible  to  produce  lighter 
sheets  or  something  of  that  sort? 

Dr.  Bean.  That  is  right.  I  merely  call  attention  to  these  factors 
for  this  reason,  that  on  the  face  of  it,  there  is  a  significant  inverse 
relationship  between  consumption  and  price.  The  report  did  not 
analyze  that  relationship  so  as  to  give  an  answer  to  the  question 
you  raise. 

With  respect  to  the  demand  for  steel  in  the  container  industry,  it 
is  the  conclusion  of  this  analysis  that  the  price  of  tin  plate  is  of  minor 
significance  in  determining  tin  plate  consumption,  and /that  in  view 
of  the  inelastic  demand  for  product^  packed  in  *  tin  cans  and  the 
relatively  small  proportion  of  the  price  represented  by  the  cost  .of 
tin  plate,  a  reduction  in  the  price  of  tiu  plate  would  be  ineffectual  in 
increasing  the  consumption  of  steel. 

This  study  fails  to  develop  any  statistical  proof  of  the  major  assump- 
tions involved  in  these  conclusions.  In  fact,  there  is  a  good  deal  of 
evidence  in  the  data  contained  in  this  report  which  the  authors- failed 
to  utilize  and  which  shows  price  of  both  tin  plate  and  of  canned  goods 
as  much  more  important  than  was  assumed  here.  In  this  study, 
there  is  no  analysis  of  the  relation  between  retail  prices  and  con- 
sumption of  canned  products  to  indicate  the  nature  of  the  elasticity 
for  canned  food  products. 

The  conclusion  that  the  elasticity  here  is  small  is  merely  inferred 
from  an  analysis  of  the  National  Resources  Committee  which  corre- 
lated national  income  with  consimiption  of  canned  fruits.  The  fact 
that  that  study  cannot  be  used  as  a  basis  for  inferring  the  nature  of 
the  relation  between  price  and  volume  consumed  and  that  the  relation 
may  actually  be  one  of  substantial  elasticity  is  suggested  by  an  exami- 
nation of  the  relation  between  the  price  of  canned  tomatoes,  the 
size  of  the  pack  of  canned  tomatoes,  and  the  price  of  tin  plate,  the  data 
being  given  in  tables  12  and  13  of  the  report.  If  we  assume  that  the 
price  of  canned  tomatoes  is  determined  by  supply  as  measured  by  the 
size  of  the  pack  and  by  the  price  of  tin  plate,  one  of  the  important 
cost  items,  it  is  possible  to  observe  both  the  nature  of  the  relation 
of  supply  to  price  and  of  the  relation  of  the  price  of  tin  plate  to  the 
price  of  a  can  of  tomatoes.  An  analysis  set  up  along  these  lines  indi- 
cates, for  example,  that  a  pack  of  14,000,000  cases  iD:the  1920's  was 
associated  with  a  price  of  13  cents  per  can,  when  the  price  of  tin  plate 
was  kept  at  $5.50  per  base  box;  and  with  a  price  of  something  under 
12  cents  when  the  nrice  of  tin  nlate  was  reduced  to  $5.20  or  $5.25. 

The  elasticity  of  demand  for  canned  tomatoes  has  changed  a  great 
deal  during  the  period  from  1923  to  1938,  if  the  relation  between  the 
size  of  the  pack  and  price  may  be  taken  as  indicative.  During  the 
1920's  it  appears  that  a  10-percent  increase  in  the  size  of  the  pack 


13726  CONCENTRATION  OJT  ECONOMIC  POWER 

was  associated  with  approximately  a  2-percent  decline  in  price,  the 
price  of  tin  plate  remaining  michanged.  In  the  more  recent  years, 
particularly  1935  to  1938,  a  10-percent  increase  in  the  size  of  the 
pack  has  been  associated  with  a  5-percent  reduction  in  price. 

These  facts  suggest  that  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  some  of  the 
canned  food  products  may  be  quite  different  from  that  assumed  by 
the  authors  of  the  analysis  of  the  demand  for  steel  in  the  container 
industry. 

Furthermore,  the  price  of  tin  plate  as  a  factor  in  determining  the 
price  of  canned  goods  may  be  more  important  than  the  authors  of 
these  studies  indicate.  This  is  suggested  by  a  comparison  that  may 
be  readily  made  between  the  price  of  tin  plate  and  the  composite 
price  of  canned  goods  as  shown  in  one  of  the  charts  on  the  board, 
and  I  shall  point  to  that  in  a  moment.  It  appears  here  that  there 
is  a  high  degree  of  correspondence  and  therefore  correlation  between 
the  price  of  tin  plate  and  the  combined  price  of  canned  tomatoes, 
peas,  and  corn.  Compared  with  the  relation  between  the  price  of 
tin  plate  and  canned  goods  prices  in  the  1920's,  the  prices  of  canned 
goods  in  the  last  5  years  have  been  relatively  low.  This  reflects 
the  effect  of  the  large  volume  of  production  of  canned  goods,  but 
except  for  that  fact  there  is  apparently  an  underlying  relation  between 
the  price  of  tin  plate  and  the  price  of  canned  goods  which  the  authors 
failed  to  investigate  and  reveal. 
-  And  graphically,  these  words  mean  this 

Mr.  Feller  (interposing).  Dr.  Bean,  do  you  want  to  have  that 
in^'-oduced  for  thg  record? 

Dr.  Bean.  Yes,  please. 

Mr.  Feller.  Mr.  Chairman,  I  should  like  to  offer  for  the  record, 
chart  entitled — I  can't  see  that  from  here. 

Dr.  Bean.  "Price  of  tin  plata  and  of  canned  goods  for  the  years 
1923  to  1938,  inclusive." 

Acting  Chairman  King.  It  will  be  received. 

(The  chart  referred  to  was  marked  "Exhibit  No.  2186"  and  is 
included  in  the  appendix  on  p.  14124.) 

Mr.  Feller.  Would  you  also  state  for  the  record  the  sources 
from  which  the  data  were  taken? 

Dr.  Bean.  The  price  of  tin  plate  is  taken  from  the  report  on  the 
demand  for  steel  in  the  container  industry,  the  one  I  am  just  now 
discussing. 

Mr.  Feller.  That  is  "Exhibit  No.  1415."  ' 

Dr.  Bean,  And  the  composite  price  of  canned  tomatoes,  peas,  and 
com  is  also  taken  from  this  report,  except  that  we  have  combined 
the  three  columns  in  one  of  the  tables  of  this  report  as  a  composite 
average. 

The  over-all  relationship  between  the  price  of  tin  plate  and  the  price 
of  these  canned  goods  is  of  this  sort,  that  for  the  years  1923  to  1928  or 
1929  you  have  both  prices  of  tin  plate  and  prices  of  canned  product? 
at  one  level.  Then  both  decline  to  approximately  the  same  level  in 
1933,  and  both  rise  sharply  in  1934.  Since  1934  the  price  of  canned 
goods  has  been  relatively  stable,  but  at  a  somewhat  lower  level  than 
would  be  indicated  by  the  previous  relation  between  tin-plate  prices 
and  canned-goods  prices,  and  I  am  suggesting  that  the  very  large 
volume  of  production  of  canned  goods  is  partly  responsible,  if  not 

>  Appendix,  p.  14010. 


OONOENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER       13727 

entirely  responsible,  for  keeping  the  price  of  canned  goods  relatively 
lower  than  the  price  of  tin  plate,  taking  the  basic  relation  between 
them  as  that  which  existed  prior  to  1925. 

The  real  significance  of  this  illustration  is  that  something  more 
probably  needs  to  be  done  in  all  of  these  analyses  in  the  way  of  relating 
the  price  of  raw  materials,  such  as  steel,  to  the  price  of  the  specific 
things  in  which  steel  is  used.  Here  we  have  a  very  definite  suggestion 
that  steel  is  a  predominant  factor  in  the  price  of  this  consumer  product, 
for  which  the  general  assumption  was  made  that  steel  prices  have 
very  little  influence. 

The  general  conclusion  that  the  price  of  tin  plate  is  of  minor  signifi- 
cance in  determining  its  consumption  is  not  borne  out  by  the  aggregate 
volume  and  price  data  given  in  this  report.  If  we  relate  the  volume  of 
total  production  of  tin  plate  as  given  in  table  9  to  the  price  of  tin  plate 
given  in  table  12  (and  adjust  the  price  for  changes  in  the  general  level 
of  prices  of  goods  other  than  farm  food  and  iron  and  steel  products 
referred  to  later),  we  find  that  the  volume  of  tin-plate  consumption 
has  been  subject  to  a  marked  expansion  in  demand  ever  since  1921, 
but  that  price  has  also  been  a  factor  in  the  volume  consumed.  On 
the  average,  price  has  been  close  to  60  percent  as  important  as  all  other 
factors  combined.  Similarly,  if  volume  of  tin-plate  output  and  indus- 
trial production  are  examined  as  factors  in  determining  the  price  of 
tin  plate,  we  find  that  tin-plate  production  is  fully  as  important,  if  not 
more  so,  than  industrial  activity  as  a  price  factor. 

Before  commenting  on  the  study  of  the  demand  for  steel  by  all 
industries  combined,  it  may  be  well  to  point  to  a  general  criticism  of 
the  price-analysis  technique  used  in  the  analyses  of  demand  for  steel 
in  the  container,  railroad,  and  automobile  industries. 

In  the  studies  on  the  demand  for  steel  in  these  industries,  the  relative 
unimportance  of  price  is  deduced  from  a  set  of  scatter  diagrams  show- 
ing the  relation  between  the  year-to-year  percentage  changes  in  price 
of  the  appropriate  kind  of  steel  and  percentage  changes  in  the  factor 
which  represents  the  use  of  steel  by  the  particular  industry.  In  the 
case  of  containers  this  latter  factor  is  the  pack  of  tomatoes,  corn,  and 
peas  separately ;  in  the  case  of  the  railroad  industry  it  is  the  deflated 
value  of  investment  by  railroads  and  railroad  steel  consumption ;  and 
in  the  case  of  the  automobile  industry  it  is  automobile  steel  consump- 
tion. None  of  these  scatter  charts  displayed  any  significant  correla- 
tion and  it  was  concluded  that  the  price  of  steel  was  of  very  little 
importance,  if  any,  in  determining  steel  consumption  in  these  indus- 
tries. 

One  of  the  difficulties  in  this  procedure  is  the  use  of  only  year-to- 
year  percentage  changes  in  one  factor  to  show  the  existence  or  absence 
of  relationship  without  taking  into  accoimt  other  factors  as  Avell.  It 
is  elementary  in  statistical  analyses  that  no  reliable  conclusions  re- 
garding the  effect  of  one  factor  on  another  can  be  drawn  unless  the 
complicating  influences  of  other  factors  known  to  be  present  have 
been  isolated.  It  is  therefore  surprising  that  there  is  no  indication 
of  any  attempt  to  include  in  this  set  of  analyses  any  of  the  factors, 
other  than  price,  which  might  affect  the  demand  for  steel  in  the  par- 
ticular industry.  Under  these  circumstances,  there  is  a  good  chance 
that  no  effect  of  price  on  steel  consumption  wouH  be  indicated  even 
if  price  variations  had  really  caused,  say,  half  the  variation  in  con- 
sumption.    This  point  we  have  ^^Iready  illasLafeed  l  .  dealing  with 


13728  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

chart  6  in  the  study  on  the  Demand  for  Steel  in  the  Automobile  In- 
dustry/ and  showed  that  where  no  negative  relationship  seemed  to 
exist,  the  addition  of  an  essential  factor  revealed  unmistakably  the 
existence  of  a  negative  relation  between  volume  of  consumption  and 
price. 

Turning  now  to  the  analysis  of  the  demand  for  steel  by  all  indus- 
tries combined,  in  contrast  with  the  foregoing  studies,  this  one  does 
make  an  attempt  to  establish  statistically  the  nature  of  price  elas- 
ticity for  steel.  Multiple  correlations  were  made  between  various 
sets  of  factors  and  the  elasticity  of  demand  was  measured  for  each 
price  quantity  regression  obtamed.  The  equations  for  nine  such 
analyses  are  given  in  the  appendix,  but  only  four  of  these  are  discussed 
in  the  text. 

All  of  these  four  analyses  are  inadequate  in  isolating  any  reliable 
estimate  of  the  elasticity  of  demand.  This  becomes  apparent  when 
we  look  beyond  the  equation,  which  we  can  do  by  plotting  the  price- 
volume  regressions  and  the  individual  observations  adjusted  for  the 
influence  of  other  factors  than  price  for  close  scrutiny,  and  if  the 
committee  will  bear  for  a  moment  with  some  of  this  technical  hngo  I 
wUl  elucidate  with  some  graphic  material. 

We  have  plotted  the  price-volume  relations  and  the  mdividual  sets 
of  data  that  they  represent  in  one  of  the-  charts.  In  the  first  of  these 
price-volume  relations  purporting  to  show  the  net  efiFect  of  price  on 
steel  ingot  production,  practically  no  influence  of  price  was  discovered 
by  the  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  analysts.  The  same  data  can,  how- 
ever, be  made  to  reveal  a  negative  relationship  between  the  price  of 
steel  and  steel  ingot  production  instead  of  the  slightly  positive  in- 
fluence found  by  the  authors  of  this  analysis,  indicating  that  the 
results  here  are,  to  my  mind,  indeterminate.  The  second  price 
quantity  relation  is  derived  from  tli-  same  data  including  two  addi- 
tional years,  1920-21,  and  the  rate  l  hange  in  industrial  production 
instead  of  a  trend  factor,  as  the  additional  elements.  The  mere  addi- 
tion of  these  two  years  gives  a  fictitious  positive  relation  between 
price  and  steel  ingot  production.  This  positive  relationship  is 
determined  entirely  by  one  point  far  beyond  the  range  of  the  other 
observations.  But  for  this  one  point  the  method  and  data  used  here 
would  give  a  statistically  insignificant  and  equally  questionable  price- 
volume  relationship. 

The  third  price-volume  relationship  is  obtained  in  an  analysis  using 
industrial  profits,  consumer  income,  and  a  composite  price  of  steel  in 
relation  to  shipments.  The  relation  of  price  to  shipments  as  indicated 
in  this  study  is  a  slightly  negative  one,  indicating  very  httle  influence 
of  price  on  volume  and  is  also  statistically  insignificant.  This  result 
also  is  determined  by  two  observations  far  remo  v'ed  from  the  range  of 
the  other  observations.  Excluding  th^^se  two  observations,"  the  nega- 
tive relation  of  price  to.  volume  is  much  more  pronounced  and  appears 
to  be  fuUy  three  times  as  important  as  a  factor-determining  volume 
than  tUe  authors  found  it  to  oe. 

The  fourth  price-volume  relation  is  obtained  by  relating  steel  book- 
ings (instead  of  shipments)  to  industrial  profits,  consumer  income,  and 
the  composite  price  tt  steel.  This  is  the  only  study  that  indicates  a 
substantial  negative  relation  between  the  price  of  steel  and  steel  book- 
ings.    The  relationship  might  be  even  more  pronounced  if  a  more 

1  "Exhibit  No.  1413,"  appendix,  p.  I39S1  at  13993. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13729 

adequate  representation  of  steel  prices  were  used  or  if  a  lag  of  several 
months  between  price  and  volume  were  taken  into  account. 

May  I  clarify  these  words  with  a  chart  containing  these  four  relation- 
ships? 

Mr.  Feller.  Mr.  Chairman,  I  offer  the  series  of  chartsentitled  "The 
Net  Regression  of  Volume  on  Price." 

(The  chart  referred  to  was  marked  "Exhibit  No.  2187"  and  is 
included  in  the  appendix  on  p.  14125.) 

Mr.  Feller.  As  I  understand  it,  these  charts  indicate  analyses  of 
data  which  was  contained  in  the  reports  submitted  by  the  United 
States  Steel  Corporation. 

Dr.  Bean.  Yes.  They  are  the  relationships  which  are  given  in  one 
of  the  tables  in  the  general  report  on  demand  for  steel,  with  these 
stated  in  four  different  equations  and  summarized  in  a  tabulation. 
Here  we  have  plotted  the  equations  and  also  the  individual  observa- 
tions that  are  given  in  the  study,  so  that  we  could  observe  whether 
or  not  the  relationships  as  given  by  the  equations  are  satisfactory. 

With  respect  to  the  first  equation,  I  find  that  it  is  necessary  to  make 
a  slight  alteration  in  the  relation  of  industrial  production  to  production 
of  steel,  getting  a  little  more  pronounced  influence  of  industrial  pro- 
duction on  steel  than  is  represented  by  the  published  equation,  and 
when  that  slight  alteration  is  made  I  find  that  the  relation  between 
price  of  steel  and  production  is  somewhat  different  from  the  one  given 
by  the  equation.  Instead  of  finding  a  positive  relationship  between 
price  and  production  I  find  somewhat  of  a  negative  relationsliip  merely 
as  a  result  of  improving  in  this  analysis  the  relation  of  industrial  pro- 
duction to  steel  production.  We  have  here  a  negative  relation  of  price 
to  volume  instead  of  the  positive  one  found  by  the  United  States  Steel 
Corporation  analysts. 

In  the  second  equation  there  is  given  a  positive  relation  of  price  to 
volume;  the  higher  the  price  the  larger  the  volume  of  steel  production. 
Note  that  there  is  just  one  point  way  outside  of  the  range  of  the 
rest  of  the  data  which  really  controls  the  slope  of  that  line,  and  by 
the  mathematical  method  used  that  is  correct.  One  point  far  removed 
from  the  body  of  the  data  controls  the  slope  of  this  relationship. 

Mr.  Feller.  Pardon  me,  Dr.  Bean,  what  is  that  point?  I  can't 
read  it. 

Dr.  Bean.  1920.  The  year  1920  in  this  analysis  shows  price  of 
steel  to  have  been  veiy  high  as  compared  with  the  prices  in  all  the 
other  years  subsequent  to  1920.  In  the  first  equation  that  year  was 
not  used,  therefore  we  found  only  a  moderate  slope  of  relation  between 
price  and  volume,  but  the  inclusion  of  that  one  year  of  very  high  prices 
necessarily  shows  a  much  greater  influence  of  price  on  volume  than 
was  obtained  in  the  other  case,  and  you  can  readily  see  that  if  that 
one  year  were  left  out  of  the  analysis  all  of  the  observations  would  be 
contained  within  a  very  limited  area,  and  that  it  would  be  difficult 
to  envision  any  kind  of  a  relationsJiip  of  price  to  volume. 

If  any  importance  is  to  be  placed  on  this  particular  part  of  the 
analysis,  you  need  to  be  aware  of  the  fact  that  it  is  controlled  almost 
entirely  by  one  observation,  that  it  that  one  observation  were  left 
out  the  result  would  be  quite  indefinite. 

With  respect  to  the  thud  equation,  I  again  find  that  the  relation  of 
price  to  volume  is  influenced  to  a  large  extent  by  two  observations, 
in  this  case  the  years  1923  and  1937  that  are  considerably  removed 


13730  CrONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

from  the  area  where  the  other  price  and  volume  data  He,  and  that  if 
these  2  years  were  left  out  of  the  analysis,  a  much  different  result 
would  be  obtained  within  this  elipse. 

(Mr.  O'Connell  assumed  the  Chair.) 

Mr.  Reynders.  May  I  ask  what  is  the  year  of  that  low  point? 

Dr.  Bean.  One  is  1938,  the  other  is  1934 

Mr.  Reynders.  Does  that  practically  balance  the  high? 

Dr.  Bean.  It  does  in  this  particular  analysis;  yes.  By  the  mathe- 
matical method  used  here  one  point  offsets  the  other  and  therefore 
you  get  a  relatively  insignificant  influence  of  price  on  volume,  but 
note  that  the  result  would  be  quite  different  if  you  leave  out  these 
2  extraneous  years. 

Mr,  Reynders.  Can't  you  leave  out  the  two  in  the  lower  ring? 

Dr.  Bean.  You  may  do  that,  but  if  you  leave  out  these  two,  then 
the  relationship  takes  on  a  steeper  slope,  which  is  more  significant 
than  the  one  contained  in  the  report.  If,  as  you  suggest,  you  leave 
out  also  1938  as  an  extraneous  year  or  as  one  that  doesn't  belong  in 
this  analysis,  then  you  still  find  that  the  relation  of  price  to  volume 
is  greater  than  the  one  indicated  here.  For  the  group  of  years  1924, 
'25,  '26,  '27,  '28,  and  '29,  the  relationship  is  not  the  one  presented 
in  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  report,  but  something  of  a  greater 
slope,  and  if  you  deal  similarly  with  the  other  years,  1930,  '31,  '32,  '33,  and 
'34,  you  again  get  a  slope  which  is  steeper  than  the  one  given  by  the 
published  equation,  so  that  accepting  your  suggestion  that  we  leave 
out  also  1938  as  well  as  '23  and  '37,  I  still  find  that  the  basic  relation- 
ship as  indicated  by  these  data  is  something  more  significant  than  that 
given  by  the  equation. 

Finally,  there  is  the  fourth  study  where  bookings  are  used  instead 
of  shipments  or  production,  and  here  we  do  find  a  substantial  relation 
of  price  to  volume.  The  report  indicates  that  the  elasticity  is  0.88, 
in  other  words  a  10-percent  increase  in  price  associated  with  close 'to 
a  9-percent  decrease  in  volume,  or  vice  versa,  and  it  is  to  me  significant 
that  the  effect  of  price  becomes  more  significant  as  these  analyses 
come  nearer  to  using  more  adequate  data  representing  demand  (in 
other  words  bookings  is  a  more  adequate  measure  of  demand  in  a 
deniand  study  than  is  the  volume  of  production). 

In  general,  it  may  be  said  that  all  of  the  foregoing  analyses  give 
such  unreliable  results  that  the  authors  themselves  discard  their  show- 
ings as  to  the  nattire  of  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  and  resort  to  the 
assumption  oi  vr  'o  elasticity  as  a  basis  for  the  further  analyses  of 
costs  in  relation  to  volume  and  of  losses  in  relation  to  price  reductions. 

In  their  conclusions  as  to  the  effect  of  a  given  price  reduction  on  the 
volume  of  steel,  the  authors  of  these  studies  fail  to  take  into  account 
the  effect  that  such  a  price  reduction  would  have  on  the  general 
average  of  price  of  goods  directly  and  indirectly  affected  by  steel 
prices.  They  also  fail  to  take  into  account  the  additional  effect  of 
the  increased  volume  of  steel  due  to  a  price  reduction  on  business  in 
general  and  therefore  on  steel,  and  that  point  Dr.  Ezekiel  elaborated 
yesterday.  That  there  is  a  positive  relation  between  steel  activity  is 
well  known  and  demonstrated  in  these  demand  studies.  They  have 
not  demonstrated  the  close  relation  that  exists  between  the  prices  of 
iron  and  steel  and  the  general  level  of  prices  of  other  goods.  In  the 
chart  labeled  "Indexes  of  prices  of  iron  and  steel  and  other  commodity 
prices,"  this  relationship  is  shown  in  a  general  way.     While  it  is  not 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13731 

possible  to  indicate  the  effect  of  prices  of  iron  and  steel  on  other  prices 
quantitatively — or  of  other  prices  on  the  prices  of  iron  and  steel — 
that  effect  nevertheless  needs  to  be  taken  into  account  in  any  analyses 
of  the  relation  of  lower  steel  prices  to  volume  and  profits  or  losses. 

And  the  chart  that  I  just  referred  to,  I  would  like  to  introduce 
into  the  record  also. 

Mr,  Feller.  I  offer  for  the  record  the  chart  entitled,  "Index  of 
Wholesale  Prices  of  Iron  and  Steel  and  of  Other  Goods,  for  the  years 
1919  to  1938,  inclusive." 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  That  will  be  admitted. 

(The  chart  referred  to  was  marked  "Exhibit  No.  2188"  and  is 
included  in  the  appendix  on  p.  14126.) 

Dr.  Bean.  The  source  of  these  data,  in  the  case  of  iron  and  steel, 
is  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Index  of  Iron  and  Steel  Prices,  the  other  price 
index  is  derived  from  the  Bureau  of  Labor  series,  the  all-commodity 
index,  by  removing  from  it  three  groups — the  group  called  farm 
products,  the  group  called  foods,  and  the  third  group,  iron  and  steel; 
so  that  we  have  here  a  comparison  annually  between  the  fluctuations 
in  the  composite  price  of  iron  and  steel  and  the  composite  of  all  other 
prices,  exclusive  of  iron  and  steel  and  exclusive  of  the  highly  variable 
prices  of  foods  and  farm  products. 

By  and  large,  there  is  a  very  close  correspondence  between  these 
two  price  indexes,  with  two  exceptions.  One  occurs  in  1923,  when 
iron  and  steel  prices  rose  quite  sharply,  as  contrasted  with  a  fairly 
stable  average  for  all  other  prices.  I  believe  that  the  series  introduced 
in  the  record  by  the  Corporation  the  other  day  of  mill  net  yields  does 
not  show  quite  this  rise  in  steel  prices  for  1923.  The  other  departure 
occurs  after  1929,  when  the  price  of  iron  and  steel  remains  at  a 
relatively  higher  level  than  the  prices  of  all  other  products,  excluding 
iron  and  steel  and  the  agricultural  products. 

But  throughout  these  years,  except  for  the  fact  of  one  index  being 
at  a  higher  level  than  the  other,  there  is  a  very  close  correspondence 
in  the  year-to-year  behavior,  and  I  introduce  this  material  for  no 
other  purpose  than  to  suggest  that  the  question  of  how  much  the 
price  of  iron  and  steel  affects  other  prices  has  not  been  answered,  and 
that  it  is  something  that  ought  to  be  fully  looked  into. 

Mr.  Reynders.  There  is  a  further  divergence  from  last  year,  of 
course? 

Dr.  Bean.  Correct.  In  1938,  steel  prices  held  at  about  the  same 
level  while  prices  of  the  other  things,  other  than  farm  and  food, 
which  went  down  slightly. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  Any  members  of  the  committee  have 
any  questions? 

Mr.  Wooden.  Dr.  Bean,  you  have  used  the  expression  "an  inverse 
relationship  between  price  and  volume."  I  think  we  all  understand 
what  that  means.  In  other  words,  as  price  decreases,  the  volume 
tends  to  increase.  You  have  also  used  the  expression  of  a  negative 
relationship  between  price  and  volume.  You  don't  mean  the  same 
thing  by  those  two  expressions,  do  you? 

Dr.  Bean.  Yes,  I  do.  A  line  that  rises  to  the  right  is,  as  a  rule, 
called  a  positively  inclined  line,  whereas  one  that  declines  to  the  right 
is  called  a  negatively  inclined  line,  and  a  negatiyely  inclined  line  in 
this  case  is  the  same  thing  as  showing  an  inve^e  relation  "between 
price  and  volume. 


13732  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Mr.  Wooden.  Js  it  your  conclusion  that  there  is  this  inverse  rela- 
tionship between  the  price  of  steel  and  the  volume  of  steel  sold,  but 
sometimes  that  relationship  is  offset  or  overcome,  or  you  might  say 
reversed,  by  the  strength  of  other  factors? 

Dr.  Bean.  Yes,  and  that  is  true  of  practically  all  other  prices,  even 
agricultural  prices. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  I  believe  there  are  no  further  ques- 
tions at  this  time.     Thank  you  very  much,  Dr.  Bean. 

Mr.  Feller.  The  next  witness  will  be  Dr.  Yntema,  recalled,  who, 
as  I  understand,  will  comment  on  Dr.  Bean's  testimony. 

TESTIMONY   OF   PROF.   THEODORE   OTTE   YNTEMA,   SCHOOL   OF 
BUSINESS,  UNIVERSITY  OF  CHICAGO,  GHICAGO,  ILL.— Resumed 

Dr.  Yntema.  Mr.  Chairman,  I  have  just  been  listening  with  great 
interest,  as  I  always  do  listen  with  great  interest  to  any  statement  by 
Dr.  Bean.  He  has  been  critical  of  some  of  the  statistical  work  which 
we  have  done,  and  I  shall  be  deeply  critical  of  some  of  the  suggestions 
which  he  has  made.  It  should  be  made  clear,  however,  that  the  area 
of  our  agreement  is  undoubtedly  far  greater  than  the  area  of  our  dis- 
agreement. I  think  that  is  a  statement  in  which  Dr.  Bean  himself 
will  probably  concur.  Tliis  is  just  a  matter  of  keeping  a  sense  of 
proportion  with  respect  to  the  criticisms  that  are  offered. 

In  evaluating  the  analyses  of  demand  which  we  submitted  to  the 
committee,  Dr.  Bean  neglected  almost  entirely  the  main  line  of  our 
argument,  and  concentrated  his  attention  on  the  secondary  evidence. 
In  our  studies  we  approached  the  problem  of  determining  elasticity  of 
demand  by  two  general  types  of  analyses.  The  first  of  these  involves 
making  a  rough  estimate  of  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  some  of  the 
principal  products  made  from  steel,  then  the  calculation  of  the  pro- 
portion of  steel  cost  to  the  price  of  these  products,  and  finally  the 
derivation  from  this  evidence  of  the  relative  response  in  the  quantity 
of  steel  sold  to  the  price  of  steel  in  each  of  the  respective  industries 
producing  these  products. 

Tnis  type  of  analysis  is  well  known  to  economists,  and  as  Dr. 
deChazeau  indicated  at  one  point  in  his  testimony,  leads  unmistakably 
to  the  conclusion  that  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  must  be  very 
low. 

Dr.  Bean  has  offered  very  little,  if  any,  criticism  of  this  type  of 
analysis,  which  constitutes,  I  may  say,  the  mainstay  of  our  conclusions. 

The  second  Hne  of  approach  which  we  employed  consisted  in  study- 
ing the  relation  of  the  quantity  of  steel  purchased  by  the  industry  to 
the  price  of  steel  and  other  important  variables  determining  its  de- 
mand. As  we  shall  indicate,  some  of  his  criticisms  of  this  analysis 
are  not  of  substantial  validity,  and  at  some  points  we  think  he  has 
not  quite  fairly  presented  the  statements  which  we  have  made. 

I  should  like  to  emphasize  that  a  considerable  part  of  Dr.  Bean's 
discussion  has  had  to  do  with  the  gross  or  unadjusted  relations  (as  he 
has  taken  care  to  point  out)  between  changes  in  the  price  of  steel  and 
changes  in  its  consumption  in  the  automobile,  container  and  railroad 
industries.  This  material  which  we  presented  was  relatively  imim- 
portant  and  could  have  been  dropped  out  entirely  from  the  studies 
without  impairing  in  any  way  their  validity. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13733 

In  criticizing  this  part  of  our  studies,  Dr.  Bean  has  failed  to  under- 
stand the  argument  we  were  making,  and  I  must  say  in  fairness  to  him 
that  we  in  turn  ought  to  be  criticized  for  faihng  to  make  our  point  clear. 
I  tliink  that  the  criticisms  in  this  case  are  with  reference  to  the  lack  of 
unambiguity  on  our  part  and  not  with  reference  to  the  content  of  the 
argument  that  we  were  trying  to  present. 

Now,  to  get  down  to  cases.  In  determining  the  demand  for  steel 
consiimed  by  the  automobile  industry,  we  based  our  conclusions 
primarily  upon  the  study  of  the  demand  for  automobiles  made  by  Roos 
and  von  Szeliski  for  General  Motors  Corporation  and  upon  the 
proportion  of  the  cost  of  steel  to  the  retail  price  of  an  automobile. 

To  this  major  part  of  our  argument,  Dr.  Bean  has  offered  no  objec- 
tion whatsoever.  Concentrating  his  attention  on  the  relatively  un- 
important part  of  the  analysis,  he  first  quoted  a  portion  of  a  sentence 
out  of  context,  thereby  distorting  its  meaning.  Referring  to  chart  6 
on  page  19  of  "Exhibit  No.  1413"^  entitled  "An  Analysis  of  the 
Demand  for  Steel  in  the  Automobile  Industry,"  he  said  that  we  claim 
that  this  scatter  diagram  showing  percentage  change  in  annual  con- 
sumption and  average  annual  price  (which  he  has  just  exhibited  to 
the  conmiittee)  "fails  to  indicate  that  lower  steel  prices  are  associated 
with  greater  quantities  of  steel  purchased  and  vice  versa." 

He  then  criticized  us  for  failing  to  attempt  to  find  from  these  data 
what  the  relationship  between  steel  consumption  and  steel  prices 
would  have  been  if  allowance  had  been  made  for  the  other  factors. 
Let  me  read  the  sentence  in  its  entirety: 

Since  the  scatter  diagram  fails  to  indicate  that  lower  steel  prices  are  associated 
with  greater  quantities  of  steel  purchased  and  vice  versa,  it  justifies  the  view  that 
price  considerations  have  a  minor  influence  in  determining  the  consumption  of 
automobile    steel. 

That  language  is  by  no  means  clear.  The  idea  we  meant  to  convey 
was  that,  in  the  past,  changes  in  the  price  of  steel  have  not  been  the 
major  determining  influence,  that  they  were  offset  or  swamped,  I 
think,  was  the  phrase  that  Dr.  Bean  iiimself  used,  by  the  effect  of 
other  influences. 

We  should  be  the  first  to  suggest  that  in  the  data  there  probably  is 
some  evidence  of  a  negative  relationship,  that  is,  an  inverse  relation- 
ship, between  changes  in  prices  and  changes  in  quantity,  although 
the  effect  of  the  change  in  price  upon  the  quantity  bought  is  very 
slight  indeed. 

Taking  these  data  in  the  scatter  diagram,  Dr.  Bean  has  attempted 
to  derive  such  a  net  relationship  between  price  and  quantity  pur- 
chased by  the  automobile  industry  through  the  technique  of  graphic 
multiple  correlation  analysis,  for  the  invention  of  which  all  statisticians 
are  greatly  indebted  to  him.  It  is  generally  recognized  that  this 
technique  is  one  of  the  most  powerful  and  also  one  of  the  most  danger- 
ous devices  for  analyzing  data.  Its  application  in  this  case  illustrates 
both  these  characteristics. 

At  one  point  in  his  discussion,  Dr.  Bean  uttered  a  profound  truth. 
I  quote: 

It  is  elementary  in  the  statistical  analyses  that  no  reliL,ble  conclusions  regarding 
the  effect  of  one  factor  or  another  can  be  drawn  unless  the  complicating  influences 
of  other  factors  known  to  be  present  have  been  isolated. 

1  Appendix,  p.  13993. 


13734       OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEU 

This  is  a  fundamental  principle,  absolutely  essential  to  the  applica- 
tion of  the  teclmique  wliich  he  has  used. 

I  suggest  to  you  that  Dr.  Bean's  analysis  fails  to  reveal  the  true, 
underlying  relationship  between  the  price  of  steel  and  the  consumption 
of  steel  in  the  automobile  industry,  because  he  has  himself  neglected 
important  complicating  factors  which  would  have  been  apparent  to 
him  if  he  had  been  in  position,  and  had  had  the  opportunity,  to  give 
the  problem  more  extended  and  intimate  study. 

If  I  may  revert  to  the  chart,  I  should  like  to  suggest  to  jou  that 
Dr.  Bean  has  either  undertaken  too  little  or  too  much.  The  mference 
that  we  intended  to  be  drawn  from  this  chart,  entitled,  "The  Relation 
of  Automobile  Steel  Price  to  Automobile  Steel  Consumption," 
appearing  on  page  19  of  exhibit  No.  1413,  was  simply  that  from  the 
scatter  of  all  of  these  observations  showing  changes  in  automobile 
steel  consumption  and  changes  in  automobile  steel  price,  it  was  not 
apparent  that  steel  price  was  the  controlling  factor.  Changes  in 
steel  prices  were  not  the  controlling  factor  in  determining  changes  in 
automobile  steel  consumption.  I  think  Dr.  Bean  would  be  the  first 
to  agree  with  that. 

We  merely  meant  to  convey  the  idea — which  we  did  not  convey 
satisfactorily,  as  witness  the  fact  that  Dr.  Bean  misinterpreted  us — we 
merely  meant  to  convey  this  idea,  that  steel  price  is  not  the  controlling 
factor,  that  there  were  other  very  important  factors  which  he  has 
himself  recognized. 

The  procedure  which  Dr.  Bean  suggested  is  nothing  new  to  us. 
We  have  spent  many  weary  days  trying  to  do  what  he  has  tried  to 
do  this  morning.  The  diiference  between  the  procedure  which  he 
employed,  however,  and  the  procedure  which  we  employed,  is  this, 
that  we  think  he  still  failed  to  take  into  account  many  variables  which 
are  extremely  important  in  this  problem,  and  that  the  inferences  which 
he  draws  from  this  chart  consequently  are  not  reliable. 

For  example.  Dr.  Bean  said  that  it  is  possible  to  consider  the  rela- 
tionship between  changes  in  automobile  steel  consumption  and  auto- 
mobile prices  in  the  years  1933,  1935,  and  1936,  and  the  years  preceding 
and  from  them,  form  some  sort  of  a  reasonable  inference  with  respect 
to  the  net  effect  of  changes  in  automobile  steel  price,  upon  automobile 
steel  consumption.  If  I  overstate  the  case,  I  hope  that  you  will 
correct  me,  Dr.  Bean. 

He  says  that  such  a  relationship  may  be  inferred  because  in  those 
years,  the  change  in  industrial  production  from  the  year  preceding 
was  of  about  the  same  level.  Now,  let  me  suggest  to  vou  that  the 
change  in  industrial  production  is  by  no  means  the  only  important 
factor  in  this  situation.  For  example,  the  change  in  consumer  income 
from  the  year  preceding  is  a  far  more  important  factor  in  changing 
the  demand  for  automobile  steel  than  changes  in  general  industrial 
production. 

A  series  of  deflated  consumer  incomes,  which  I  confess  is  none  too 
satisfactory,  exhibited  the  following  characteristics:  In  1933,  there 
was  a  decrease  in  deflated  consumer  income  of  3.6  percent;  in  1935, 
an  increase  of  3.5  percent;  and  in  1936,  an  increase  of  13.1  percent. 

In  the  second  place,  the  changes  in  the  purchase  of  steel  by  the 
automobile  industry  reflect  the  mcreases  or  the  decreases  of  their 
inventories.  If  you  want  to  find  the  underlying  relationship,  neglect- 
ing changes  in  mventory,  betv^een  the  percentage  change  in  price 


CX)NC?ENTRAT1UN  OF  ECONOMIC  I'OWI^R  13735 

and  the  percentage  change  in  consumption,  that  factor  is  an  ex- 
tremely important  one,  particularly,  I  should  say,  in  the  year  1933, 
when  we  moved  from  a  period  of  declining  busmess  to  a  period  of 
advancing  business. 

In  the  third  place,  I  should,  for  your  consideration,  point  out  the 
fact  that  Senator  Kling  so  aptly  cited  a  few  minutes  ago,  and  that 
is  whether  or  not  the  change  in  psychological  attitude  on  the  part  of 
those  who  buy  automobiles  and  those  who  produce  the  automobiles, 
whether  the  changes  in  psychological  attitude  from  the  year  pre- 
ceding, in  1933  as  compared  with  1932,  in  1935  as  compared  with 
1934,  and  in  1936  as  comi)ared  with  1935,  were  in  fact  the  same. 
That  happens  to  be  a  very  important  factor  in  the  demand  for  auto- 
mobiles and  the  demand  for  steel  in  the  production  of  automobiles, 
and  I  submit  to  you  that  those  changes  were  not  in  fact  the  same. 

In  the  fourth  place,  the  demand  for  automobiles  and  the  demand 
for  the  steel  in  them  depend  upon  the  proportion  of  automobiles  in 
existence  which  are  about  to  be  scrapped,  and  the  changes  in  that 
situation  from  the  year  preceding.  I  should  raise  the  question  as  to 
whether  or  not  the  change  in  that  factor  actually  remained  the  same. 
I  say  there  is  some  difference  in  that  factor  which  ought  not  to  be 
neglected. 

There  is  still  a  further  question  that  ought  to  be  considered,  whether 
or  not  the  changes  in  the  prices  of  other  related  products  from  1932 
to  1933,  from  1934  to  1935,  and  from  1935  to  1936,  were  substantially 
the  same,  because  those  changes  in  the  other  prices  are  related  to  this 
net  relationship  which  you  are  inclined  to  find  between,  automobile 
steel  consumption  and  automobile  steel  prices. 

The  reason  we  did  not  pursue  this  particular  line  of  attack  is  that 
we  did  not  have  confidence  in  it.  As  1  said  before,  I  suggested  to  you 
that  Dr.  Bean  has  either  tried  to  do  too  much  or  has  done  too  little, 
because  the  only  conclusion  I  would  be  willing  to  derive  from  this 
information  presented  to  you  this  morning  is  that  the  price  of  steel  is 
not  the  controlling  force  in  determining  the  quantity  of  steel  con- 
sumption; that  it  is  swamped  by  other  forces.  I  do  not  think  that 
there  would  be  substantial  disagreement  about  that. 

If  you  get  into  the  study  of  net  relationships,  you  are  getting  into 
exceedingly  dangerous  territory.  We  recognized  that  in  the  multiple 
correlation  analysis,  and  we  wrote  page  after  page,  pointing  out  the 
qualifications  to  which  any  such  analysis  must  be  subjected,  and  we 
used  extreme  care  in  making  plain  those  qualifications. 

In  continuing  with  the  discussion  of  the  relation  between  the  price 
of  steel  and  its  consumption  in  the  automobile  industry,  Dr.  Bean 
dealt  with  the  problem  of  the  variation  in  the  steel  consumed  per 
automobile  in  relation  to  the  price  of  steel.  In  attacking  that  par- 
ticular problem,  he  employed  data  which  we  discarded  because  they 
were  not  applicable  to  the  purpose.  He  took  the  reported  figures  on 
steel  consumption  in  the  industry  and  divided  it  by  the  number  of 
cars,  to  obtain  the  average  steel  consumed  per  car.  That  neglects 
the  effect  of  inventory  changes  in  the  hands  of  the  automobile  com- 
panies. We  considered  using  the  material  and  discarded  it  for  that 
particular  purpose  because  the  data  were  not  as  satisfactory  an  indica- 
tion of  the  steel  per  car  as  is  obtained  by  the  use  of  average  weights 
per  car.  Those  data  appear  on  page  23  of  "Exhibit  No.  1413,"  and 
with  reference  to  that  particular  set  of  materials,  Dr.  Bean  has  offered 


13736       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

no  criticism  whatever,  I  suggest  to  the  committee  that  that  is 
the  appropriate  study  and  the  materials  which  he  used  arc  far  loss  satis- 
factory for  that  purpose. 

In  dealing  with  the  study  of  the  demand  for  steel  in  the  container 
industry,  Dr.  Bean  did  not  go  into  such  great  detail  and  it  is  therefore 
not  possible  for  me  to  offer  such  specific  criticism  of  his  comments. 
There  are  one  or  two  points,  however,  that  I  do  not  think  should  be 
passed  by  without  some  comment. 

He  said: 

If  we  assume  that  the  price  of  canned  tomatoes  is  determined  by  supply,  as 
measured  by  the  size  of  the  pack  and  by  the  price  of  tin  plate,  one  of  the  important 
cost  items,  it  is  possible  to  observe  both  the  nature  of  the  relation  of  supply  to 
price  and  of  the  relation  of  the  price  of  tin  plate  to  the  price  of  a  can  of  tomatoes. 

Now,  if  you  are  considering  the  demand  side  of  the  situation,  and 
you  have  the  size  of  the  pack,  that  is,  the  quantity  of  tomatoes  packed 
to  be  sold,  and  that  pack  is  sold,  I  cannot  see,  and  I  do  not  see,  how 
anybody  else  could  find  that  the  price  of  tin  plate  is  a  relevant  factor 
in  determining  the  price  of  tomatoes.  It  is  the  quantity  of  tomatoes 
sold  in  the  packed  form  that  determines  the  price.  The  price  of  tin 
plate  might  be  higher  or  lower  but  it  would  have  no  effect  whatever 
upon  the  price  of  tomatoes.     That  is  simply  elementary  economics. 

Mr.  Reynders.  In  that  connection,  could  you  refresh  your  memory 
as  to  what  the  fluctuation  in  the  price  of  tin  plate,  what  effect  that 
would  have  on  the  price  of  a  can  of  tomatoes? 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  evidence  on  that 

Mr.  Reynders  (interposing).  I  am  speaking  now  of  the  fluctuation 
in  price,  not  the  price  itself. 

Dr.  Yntema.  The  fluctuations  in  the  price  of  tin  plate  were  rela- 
tively small  over  this  period,  ranging  from  $5.50  to  $4.43  per  base  box, 
a  change  of  something  in  the  neighborhood  of  20  to  25  percent.  The 
proportion  of  the  cost  of  tin  plate  to  the  price  of  the  goods  «old  at  retail 
is  about  10  percent.  That  would  mean  that  the  effect  upon  the  final 
price  of  canned  goods  would  be  approximately  10  percent  of  the  25 
percent,  or  in  the  neighborhood  of  2  or  3  percent.  That  would  be  the 
effect  which  you  would  expect  if  it  is  passed  on  entirely  to  the  consumer 
of  the  product. 

May  I  revert  again  to  one  of  Dr.  Bean's  charts?  Dr.  Bean  pre- 
sented this  chart  showing  the  price  of  tin  plate  and  of  canned  goods, 
numbered  "Exhibit  No.  2186."  This  represents  the  price  of  ^tin  plate 
from  1923  through  1938  and  also  the  price  of  canned  tomatoes,  peas, 
and  corn.  I  cannot  quote  Dr.  Bean  precisely  in  his  comments  on  the 
chart,  but  if  I  understood  him  correctly,  he  conveyed  the  idea  that 
thi;  chart  suggests  that  these  fluctuations  in  the  price  of  tin  plate 
have  been  of  some  substantial  importance  in  affecting  the  price  of 
canned  tomatoes,  peas,  and  corn. 

Now,  Dr.  Bean  has  pointed  out  at  some  length  the  importance  of 
keeping  constant  the  effect  of  other  important  variables,  and  it  seems 
to  me  that  it  is  not  possible  at  all  to  draw  any  reliable  conclusion  from 
these  two  series  unless  we  do  exactly  what  ne  has  told  us  we  should 
do  namely,  allow  for  the  effecj:  of  changes  in  the  general  price  level 
and  the  national  income,  which  also  showed  somewhat  similar  fluctua- 
tions during  this  period. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  If  they  did  show  somewhat  similar 
variations,  would  it  change  the  character  of  the  relationship? 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13737 

Dr.  Yntem\.  It  would  make  the  answer  indeterminable.  I  don't 
say  that  there  is  nothing  whatsoever  to  Dr.  Bean's  suggestion;  I 
simply  say  that  it  is  incorrect  statistical  procedure,  to  infer,  from 
the  evidence  which  has  been  presented,  that  fact.  If  you  did  have  the 
other  evidence,  the  three  series  would  move  so  much  alike  that  the 
precision  of  any  inference  you  could  make  would  be  far  less  than  might 
appear  upon  a  supei-ficial  examination  of  these  data. 

Dr.  Bean  said: 

In  the  studies  on  the  demand  for  steel  in  the  container,  railroad  and  automobile 
industries,  the  relative  unimportance  of  price  is  deduced  from  a  set  of  scatter 
diagrams  showing  the  relation  between  the  year-to-year  percentage  changes  in 
price  of  the  appropriate  kind  of  steel,  and  percentage  changes  in  the  factor  which 
represents  the  use  of  steel  b^-  the  particular  industry. 

Merely  again  to  obtain  the  proper  perspective,  that  was  decidedly 
secondary  evidence,  and  w^e  did  not  deduce  the  relative  importance 
from  that  evidence;  we  merely  used  that  material  to  point  out  that 
other  factors  as  well  as  price  were  of  controlling  importance  in  deter- 
mining the  quantity  of  steel  bought  by  the  various  industries.  Our 
analyses  would  not  be  one  whit  less  convincing  if  that  material  were 
eliminated  entirely  from  them.  In  fact,  some  criticis  have  told  me 
that  they  tliink  that  our  presentation  would  be  improved  by  that 
omission.     I  think  that  is  a  fairly  debatable  point. 

In  general,  then,  summing  up  Dr.  Bean's  criticism  of  the  use  of 
these  scatter  diagrams,  I  suggest,  first,  that  we  have  failed  to  make 
ourselves  clear  on  them,  that  the  point  wliich  we  intended  to  convey 
is  a  perfectly  proper  point,  but  that  we  may  perhaps  have  used  not 
quite  entirely  unambiguous  language,  and  if  so,  that  fault  is  ours  and 
we  appreciate  his  calling  it  to  our  attention. 

In  the  second  place,  we  should  deny  that  it  is  so  easy  to  ascertain 
from  inspection  of  these  charts  the  sort  of  negative  relationship  which 
he  -has  pointed  out.  The  problem  is  far  more  complicated  than  he 
has  made  it.  I  suggest  once  more  that  either  we  must  do  more  than 
he  has  indicated  or  otller^vise,  simply  make  the  rough  inference  which 
we  did  make. 

Finally,  Dr.  Bean  offered  some  suggestions  with  reference  to  the 
analysis  of  the  demand  for  steel  by  multiple  correlation  methods, 
and  I  should  like  to  respond  to  them. 

This  net  chart  of  Dr.  Bean's  is  entitled,  "The  Nqt  Regression  of 
Volume  on  Price,"  and  is  numbered  "Exhibit  No.  218f." 

The  question  might  be  raised,  "Why  did  we  incorporate  in 
"Exhibit  No.  1411"  ^  a  study  showing  a  net  relationship  that  as  price 
goes  up  the  average  production  and  consumption  of  steel  by  all 
consuming  industries  increases." 

The  same  question  might  be  raised  with  respect  to  Relationship 
II.  Now,  we  did  not  intend  to  convey  to  the  committee  or  to  anyone 
reading  this  report,  that  is  "Exhibit  No.  1411"  (and  I  think  that  a 
simple  reading  of  our  text  will  indicate  as  much)  that  we  thought 
that  these  relations,  i.  e.,  Relationships  I  and  II  in  this  exhibit, 
represented  actually  how  consumption  and  production  of  steel  would 
vary  with  price.  The  fact  that  we  did  present  them  ought  to  be 
taken  as  evidence  of  good  faith,  to  show  how  difficult  it  is  to  find  the 
true  relationship  by  this  method. 

'  Appendix,  p.  13913. 


13738  OONOKNTIIATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Frankly,  I  should  say  that  in  Relationship  I,  as  we  have  pointed 
out  in  the  document  entitled  "A  Statistical  Analysis  of  the  Demand 
for  Steel,  1919-38,"  "Exhibit  No.  1411",  we  think  that  we  have  not 
taken  entirely  satisfactory  variables  into  account. 

In  that  particular  study  we  investigated  the  relationship  between 
the  fluctuation  of  production  of  steel  ingots  and  castings  and  the  price 
of  steel  and  industrial  production  and  a  time  trend.  The  inference 
to  be  drawn  from  this  study  is  that  price  of  steel,  industrial  produc- 
tion, and  time  trend  do  not  account  with  entire  satisfaction  for  the 
production  of  steel  ingots  and  castings.  It  is  a  cardinal  principle  in 
statistics  that  when  your  results  don't  make  sense  you  discard  them. 
In  this  particular  case  I  should  say  that  the  results  do  not  conform 
entirely  with  expectations  and  that  the  analysis  must  therefore  be 
carried  further, 

Mr.  Lewis.'  In  both  of  these  relationships  we  very  carefully 
pointed  out  in  "Exhibit  No.  1411"  that  the  basic  data  on  which  they 
were  computed  were  inadequate  for  drawing  any  conclusion  from 
them,  and  we  ourselves  did  not  draw  any  conclusions  from  them.  In 
several  pages  we  pointed  out  that  steel  ingot  production  was  not  a 
satisfactory  measure  of  steel  sales,  nor  was  industrial  production,  on 
the  other  hand,  a  satisfactory  measure  of  the  shifts  in  demand 
assuming  price  constant. 

Dr.  Yntema.  From  our  own  i-eport,  "Exhibit  No.  1411"  therefore, 
you  can  read  without  difficulty  that  we  did  not  attach  great  significance 
to  this  finding.  It  would  have  made  a  far  better  appearing  report  if 
we  had  simply  omitted  tliis  entirely  (referring  to  Relationships  I  and  II) 
and  present  ad  just  one  result.  We  elected,  however,  to  show  to  the 
committee  what  was  involved  in  this  sort  of  study  and  to  give  some 
idea  of  the  qualifications  which  must  be  kept  in  mind  in  interpreting  it. 

The  point  that  Dr.  Bean  has  raised  with  respect  to  Relationship  II 
in  this  "Exhibit  No.  2187"  ^  is  certainly  correct,  that  the  slope  of  this 
line  representing  how  production  fluctuates  in  relation  to  the  composite 
price  of  finished  steel  is  determined  largely  by  this  one  observation  for 
1920,  and  no  statistician  would  therefore  attach  great  weight  to  it. 
We  did  not  attacji  any  great  significance  either  to  this  particular 
finding. 

In  Relationship  III  we  find  that  the  average  behavior  of  shipments 
of  steel  in  relation  to  price  is  such  that  as  price  goes  up  shipments  go 
down.  Dr.  Bean  has  suggested  that  if  we  eliminate  two  observations 
1937  and  1923,  from  this  Relationship  III,  that  the  average  line  of 
relationship  would  be  steeper.  Well,  that  of  course  is  no  basis  for 
statistical  procedure.  Merely  because  two  points  fail  to  conform  to 
the  others  is  no  basis  for  eliminating  those  points.  If  there  were  a  sound 
logical  reason  for  eliminating  those  two  particular  points,  then  their 
elimination  ought  to  be  considered,  but  it  is  one  of  the  worst  types  of 
statistical  manipulation  to  omit  ]^oints  merely  because  they  happen 
to  fail  to  conform  to  the  rest  of  the  observations. 

May  I  suggest  this,  please.  I  am  not  accusing  Dr.  Bean  of  poor 
statistical  technique.  Dr.  Bean  is  one  of  the  best  statisticians  whose 
acquaintance  it  is  my  pleasure  to  have  made.  I  am  merely  suggesting 
that  Dr.  Bean's  point  is  a  good  one  that  you  ought  to  investigate 
whether  there  is  some  characteristic  which  those  points  have,  and  I 

'  Harold  Gregg  Lewis,  economist,  University  of  Chicago.    See  supra,  p.  13650. 
»  Appendix,  p.  14125. 


CONC?ENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  TOWER  13739 

think  that  that  should  be  taken  mto  account  in  going  further  with  the 
analysis. 

Mr.  Lewis.  May  I  interrupt?  In  the  first  place,  Dr.  Bean  has  said 
that  if  we  actually  eliminated  these  two  observations  we  should  get  a 
net  relationship  between  price  and  volume,  which  would  be  approxi- 
mately three  times  as  large  as  the  one  we  actually  obtained.  Of  course 
even  if  we  did  that,  our  result  would  still  be  significantly  less  than  unit 
elasticity.  Even  if  we  eliminated  these  points,  the  final  conclusion  we 
would  get  would  be  that  changes  in  steel  price  do  not  lead  to  larger 
proportional  changes  in  steel  volume.  Actually,  since  this  report ' 
was  written — unfortunately  Dr.  Bean  has  not  had  an  opportunity  to 
study  the  data  in  the  same  way  that  we  have — I  have  attempted  to 
account  for  the  fact  that  these  observations,  1937,  1923,  1924,  1938, 
1933,  are  extreme  observations.  I  have  found  that  if  we  include  addi- 
tional factors  such  as  the  rate  of  change  in  the  price  of  steel,  that  is, 
essentially,  if  we  study  speculative  buying  of  steel,  that  these  points 
lie  very  close  to  this  line.  Not  only  is  that  true,  but  our  results  lead 
us  to  the  conclusion  that  actually  the  elasticity  we  should  so  obtain 
would  be  lower  than  the  elasticities  which  were  obtained  in  this  report. 
Dr.  Bean's  major  comment  on  this  last  relationship  in  which  steel 
bookings  are  related  to  composite  price  of  steel,  industrial  profits,  and 
consumer  income,  is  that  first  we  have  probably  used  an  inadequate 
measure  of  price.  I  do  not  quite  understand  what  criticism  he  has  of 
that  price.  However,  may  I  point  out  that  since  this  computation 
was  made,  we  have  actually  used  the  index  of  mill  yet  yield,  which  is  a 
very  carefully  constructed  mill  net  index,  and  we  have  found  if  we  sub- 
stituted that  index  for  the  price  we  used  in  the  report,  entitled  "A 
Statistical.  Analysis  of  the  Demand  for  Steel,  1919-38",  "Exhibit 
No.  1411,"  that  our  results  would  not  be  changed  significantly. 

Secondly,  he  has  suggested  in  connection  with  this  last  relationship 
that  if  we  lag  price  or  consumption,  we  should  probably  get  a  some- 
what different  result.  I  should  agree  with  that,  but  in  order  to  dem- 
onstrate the  reasonableness  of  such  a  lag,  he  should  have  to  give  some 
underlying  logic  whereby  "that  lag  could  be  given  some  definite 
economic  meaning. 

Dr.  Yntema,  May  I  offer  in  conclusion  just  a  few  remarks?  The 
area  of  agreement  is  far  greater  than  that  of  disagreement,  and  Dr. 
Bean  and  I,  I  am  sure,  do  not  have  substantially  different  views  in 
these  matters,  and  I  want  to  emphasize  this  point,  that  part  of  the 
difficulty  has  arisen  due  to  our  own  fault  in  not  making  perfectly 
clear  what  we  intended  to  show. 

There  is  one  point  to  which  Dr.  Bean  reverted  in  concluding  his 
testirnony  with  respect  to  our  alleged  failure  to  take  into  accouht  the 
additional  effect  of  the  inpreased  volume  of  steely  due  to  a  price  re- 
duction, on  business  in  general,  and,  therefore,  on  steel.  This  is  the 
same  point  that  Dr.  Ezekiel  made  yesterday,  and  smce  we  are  to 
discuss  Dr.  Ezekiel's^  statement  tomorrow,  I  should  like  to  defer 
comment  on  this  particular  point  until  that  time. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  I  would  like  to  recess  now.  Wha,t 
is  your  pleasu^^e? 

Mr;  Feller.  Dr.  Bean  wanted  to  make  one  observation. 
Dr.  Bean.  Just  two  comments.     I  do  not  believe  I  was  unfair  in 
the'  quotation  from  "E.xhibit  No.   14.13"  that  I  cited  in  respect  to 

■  "Exhibit  No.  Hir'.'appendix,  p.  1.391J?. 
124491— 41— pt.  26 11 


13740       OONOENTRATION  GF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

chart  6  of  that  exhibit.^  If  any  of  you  will  read  it,  leave  off  the  word 
"since,"  and  the  last  phrase  in  that  sentence,  and  you  will  get  the 
gist  of  what  the  authors  apparently  had  in  mjjid.  I  tried  to  find 
their  thouglit.  The  only  place  where  I  could  find  it  was  in  that  par- 
ticular sentence  to  which  they  have  added  the  word  "since,"  and  I 
don't  think  the  word  "since"  alters  the  meaning  of  that  sentence. 

The  second  point,  as  to  whether  or  not  this  material  has  been  pre- 
sented to  the  committee  in  such  a  way  as  to  leave  with  the  committee  a 
full  understanding  of  the  complications,  the  inadequacies  and  all  the 
rest.  It  is  my  impression  that  the  reports  do  not  quite  do  that  job,  and 
I  turn  for  the  moment  to  page  28  ^  of  the  "Analysis  of  the  Demand  for 
Steel"  ("Exhibit  No.  1411")  reading  next  to  the  last  paragraph  on  that 
page:  "In  the  graphical  analyses  that  were  made  of  the  various  de- 
mand relations,  there  were  clear  indications  that  if  the  lags  of  ship- 
ments and  industrial  profits  behind  bookings  were  removed,  Relations 
III  and  IV  would  both  give  about  the  same  results  for  the  elasticity  of 
demand,  yielding  a  figure  of  0.3  to  0.4."  It  is  the  next  sentence  I 
really  have  in  mind.  "The  evidence  and  argument  adduced  in  the 
preceding  pages  of  this  paper  support  the  conclusion  that  such  a 
value — or  one  even  lower — for  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  is 
not  a  statistical  happenstance,  but  a  reality." 

I  would  underscore  the  word  "reality,"  It  is  my  impression  that 
this  particular  paragraph  which  will  be  generally  read — if  anything 
is  read  in  these  reports  it  will  be  paragraphs  of  that  sort  and  not  the 
equations  and  not  the  qualifications — gives  much  greater  importance 
to  the  analyses  contained  in  these  reports  than  I  think  the  analyses 
are  entitled  to.  Finally,  if  these  analyses  are  not  entitled  to  be  taken 
with  a^reat  deal  of  reliability,  then  I  would  say  to  Dr.  Yntema  that 
they  should  not  have  been  included  with  the  implication  that  they 
corroborate  his  basic  conclusions.- 

Dr.  Yntema.  May  I  comment?  I  think  we  aU  owe  a  debt  of 
gratitude  to  Dr.  Bean  for  bringing  out  more  clearly  in  the  discussion 
considerations  which  ought  to  be  kept  in  mind  in  evaluating  the 
evidence.  I  should  like  to  call  his  attention  to  a  word  in  the  sen- 
tence which  he  read.  This  sentence  begins,  "The  evidence  and  argu- 
ment"— If  I  had  used  as  the  subject  of  that  sentence  "statistical 
analyses",  without  any  logical  argument  accompanying  it,  I  should 
never  have  stated  that  conclusion.  The  reasort  why  we  concluded 
that  the  low  elasticity  demand  for  steel  is  not  a  statistical  happen- 
stance but  a  reality  is  that  it  "made  sense." 

Mr.  Feller.  Mr.  Chairman,  before  we  adjourn,  and  I  suggest  that 
we  adjourn  until  10:30  tomorrow  morning,  I  should  like  to  express  on 
behalf  of  Dr.  Kreps  his  profound  gratitude  to  the  Steel  Corporation, 
to  Dr.  Yntema,  to  his  staff,  and  to  Drs.  deChazeau,  Taitel,  Ezekiel, 
and  Bean  for  their  work  in  bringing  out  this  important  material.  On 
behalf  of  myself  I  should  like  to  make  just  one  observation.  Ever 
since  I  heard  of  the  science  of  econometrics,  I  have  been  very  skeptical 
of  it.  After  Ustenmg  to  the  most  eminent  practitioners  of  tliat  science 
or  art,  my  skepticism  has  not  been  substantially  lessened.  Mr. 
Justice  Holmes  once  said  that  a  page  of  history  is  worth  a  volume  of 
logic,  and  after  listemng  to  the  discussion  here,  I  wondered  whether 

•  Appendixp.  13993. 

>  Of  the  original  document. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13741 

it  cpuldn't  be  paraphrased  by  saying  a  page  of  business  facts  is  worth 
a  vokime  of  econometrics. 

Acting  Chairman  O'Connell.  I  think  that  the  committee  has  the 
same  view  that  you  do  as  to  paying  our  tribute  to  Dr.  Yntema  and 
his  staff  for  the  work  they  have  done,  and  on  behalf  of  the  committee, 
I  also  want  to  thank  Dr'  deChezeau,  Dr.  Ezekiel,  Dr.  Bean,  and  Mr. 
Taitol  for  the  work  they  did  in  helping  to  present  this  rather  com- 
plicated picture  to  the  committee. 

We  will  recess  now  until  10:30  tomorrow  mormng. 

(Whereupon  at  12:25  p.  m.,  the  committee  recessed  until  10:30 
a.  m.,  Friday,  January  26,  1940.) 


(Testimony  on  the  Iron  and  Steel  Industry  is  resumed  and  con- 
cluded in  Hearings,  Part  27.) 


APPENDIX 


The  following  exhibits,  Nos.  1409  to  1418,  were  introduced  and 
ordered  to  be  placed  on  file  with  the  committee  during  Hearings, 
Part  20.  They  were  subsequent!}'  ordered  to  be  printed  and  are 
reproduced  herewith,  with  the  exception  of  "Exhibit  No.  1418,"  which 
is  included  in  Hearings,  Part  27. 

Exhibit  No.   1409 

Table  of  Contents 

section  a financial 

Title  Of  Chart 
Assets,  From  1901 
Assets,  1938  Compared  with  1901 
Capital,  Surplus  and  Liabilities 
Earnings  and  Cash  Dividends 

Earnings  and  Cash  Dividends  per  Share  of  Common  Stock 
Ratio  of  Earnings  to  Net  Assets: 

From  1920 

From  1902 
Distribution  of  the  Sales  Dollar,  1929-1938,  inclusive 
Distribution  of  the  Sales  Dollar,  Year  1938 
Payroll  and  Earnings  per  Dollar  of  Sales 
Payments  to  Employees  and  to  Investors  per  Dollar  of  Sales 
Taxes  per  Dollar  of  Sales 

Total  Taxes  and  Earnings  Available  for  Dividends 
Assets,  Earnings  and  Taxes,  1937-1938  Compared  with  1902 
State  and  Local  Taxes 

Taxes  (State  and  Local,  Federal,  and  Social  Security) 
Taxes  Paid  in  1937  and  1938 

Average  Assets,  Annual  Sales  and  Earnings,  1929-1938,  inclusive 
Ratio  of  Sales  to  Total  Assets  (U.  S.  Steel  and  Other  Companies),  year  1938 
Average  Monthly  Prices  of  Common  and  Preferred  Stocks 

SECTION    B COSTS 

Relationship  between  Total  Costs  of  Operation  and  Volume  of  Business,  1938 

Conditions 
Composition  of  Total  Costs  of  Operation  in  Relation  to  Volume  of  Business 
Relationship  between  Sales  and  Costs — Effect  of  Reduction  from  Average  1938 

Prices' 
Increases  in  Volume  Needed    to    Compensate   for  Various  Decreases  in    1938 

Prices  Compared  to  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume 
Estimated   Additions  to    1938  Deficit — How  Deficit  Would  have  Increased  If 

Prices  Had  Been  Reduced 
Relationship  between  Sales  and  Costs — Effect  of  Reduction  from  2nd  Half  1938 

Pirices 
Increases  n  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Various  Decreases  in  2nd  Half 

1938  Prices  Compared  to  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume 
Unadjusted  Costs  and  Volume  of  Business  Compared  with  Estimated  Costs  for, 

Corresponding  Volumes  under  1938  Conditions 
How  Costs  Have  Increased,  1938  Compared  with  1931 
How  Costs  Have  Increased,  1937  Compared  with  1929-1930  Average 

13743 


13744  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

SECTION    C PRICES 

Title  of  Chart 
Composite  Mill  Net  Yield  and  CosJ,  per  Weighted  Ton  Shipped  (1926=  100) 
Average  Yearly  Base  Prices  of  Principal  Steel  Products  (1924  =  100) 
Reported  Base  Price  and  Mill  Net  Yield: 

Heavy  Structural  Shapes  at  Pittsburgh 

Heavy  Structural  Shapes  at  Chicago 

Plates  at  Pittsburgh 

Bars  at  Pittsburgh 

Bars  at  Chicago 

Standard  Pipe  at  Pittsburgh 

Cold  Rolled  Sheets 
Reported  Composite  Price  and  Composite  Mill  Net  Yield  (1926=  100) : 

From  1926 

From  1912 
Proportion  of  Steel  Cost  in  Price  of  Finished  Product,  1938 
Automobile  Steel  Consumption  and  Steel  Prices  in  United  States 
Automobile  Steel  Consumption  and  Automobile  Production  in  United  States 
The  Basing  Point  Method  of  Quoting  Delivered  Prices: 

Diagram  1 

Diagram  2 

Diagram  3 

Diagram  4 

Diagram  5 

Diagram  6 

Diagram  7 

Diagram  8 

Diagram  9 

Diagram  10 

Diagram  11 
The  Uniform  F.  O.  B.  Mill  Price  Systeip: 

Market  Territories  of  Major  Mills  Producing  Steel  Sheets 

Detailed  Map  of  Counties  in  E.  Ohio  and  W.  Pennsylvania 
Explanation  of  Unadjusted  and  Adjusted  Freight  Absorption 
Average  Delivered  Price  and  Freight  Absorption  (U.  S.  Steel       'rporation  Sub 

sidiaries),  February,  1939 
Average  Delivered  Price  and  Freight  Absorption  (Selected  Producing  Companies), 

February,  1939 
Breakdown  of  Average  Delivered  Price  (U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries), 

February,  1939 
Breakdown  of  Average  Delivered  Price  (Selected  Producing  Companies),  Feb- 
ruary, 1939 
Relation  of  Mill  Net  Yield  and  Reported  Base  Price,  February,  1939 

SECTION    D CAPACITY    AND    PRODUCTION 

Total  Ingot  Capacity  (U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries  and  Other  Steel  Pro- 
ducing Companies) 

Steel  Ingot  Capacity  Compared  with  Population  (U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  Sub- 
sidiaries and  Total  United  States) 

Total  Ingot  Production  (U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries  and  Other  Steel 
Producing  Companies) 

Steel  Ingot  Production  Compared  with  Population  (Total  United  States) 

Ingot  Capacity  and  Production  (U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries) 

Ingot  Capacity  and  Production  (Total  United  States) 

Per  Cent  of  Ingot  Capacity  Operated  (U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries) 

Steel  Production  and  Manufacturing  Production  (Federal  Reserve  Indexes, 
1923-1925=100) 

World  Ingot  Production  (By  Principal  Steel  Producing  Countries),  1929,  1937 
and  1938 


CONOENTKATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13745 


SECTION    E LABOR 

Title  of  Chart 

Number  of  Employees  and  Ingot  Production  (1929=100) 

Actual  Number  of  Employees  and  Number  That  Would  Have  Been  Required  on 
Basis  of  1929  Hours  per  Week 

Ingot  Production  and  Number  of  Employees  (U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  Sub- 
sidiaries, 1929=100),  1937  Compared  with  1929 

Ingot  Production  and  Numl^er  of  Employees  (Total  Steel  Industry,  1929=100), 
1937  Compared  with  1929 

Employment  and  Payroll  by  Classes  of  Employees,  1937-1938  Average 

Employees  by  Age  Groups,  May  1,  1938 

Skilled*  Semi-skilled  and  Common  Labor  Employees,  Year  1938 

Payroll  and  Component  Factors  (1929=100) 

Wages  and  Hours  (U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  Manufacturing  Subsidiaries) 

Wages  and  Hours  (U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  Manufacturing  Subsidiaries  and  All 
Manufacturing  Industries) 

Average  Weekly  Earnings  Compared  with  Cost  of  Living  (1929=100) 

Wage  Rates  and  Steel  Prices  (1914=100) 

Average  Earnings  per  Hour  and  Common  Labor  Rate 

"Earnings  per  Hour  and  Steel  Prices  (1926=100) 

Earnings  per  Hour  and  Production,  April,  193V -November  ,1939,  inclusive 


SECTION    F — MISCELLANEOUS 


Flow  Chart  of  Steelmakinj 


Section  A — Financial 

Assets — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Fixed  Assets 
(Land,  Buildings, 
Equipment,  Etc.) 


Current  Assets 
(Cash,  Invento- 
ries, Etc.) 


1901 
1902. 
1903. 
1904 
1905 
1906 
1907. 
1908 
1909. 
1910. 
1911. 
1912. 
1913. 
1914. 
1915. 
1916. 
1917. 
1918. 
1919. 
1920. 
1921. 
1922. 
1923. 
1924. 
1925. 
1926. 
1927- 
1928. 
1929. 
1930. 
1931. 
1932. 
1933. 
1934. 
1935. 
1936. 
1937. 
1938. 


1,291,883, 
.,  300,  521, 
,328,132, 
,  336,  882, 
,330,097, 
,  320,  077, 
,  372,  972, 
,  393,  522, 
,  401,  507, 
,  430,  212, 
,  460, 303, 
,  448,  175, 
,  465,  498, 
,  457,  853, 
,  443,  300, 
,472,623, 
,  521,  836, 
,  563, 937, 
,573,661, 
,  606,  758, 
,  644,  795, 
,631.579, 
,639,158, 
,  078,  208, 
,  692, 197, 
,  667,  391, 
,  709,  779, 
,661,123, 
,  541,  492, 
,  677,  327, 
,  683,  982, 
,  650. 816, 
,  653, 923, 
,  626, 143, 
,  338,  522, 
,  350,  037, 
,410.432, 
,  166,  519, 


$190, 644,  992 
211,276,652 
216,  079,  027 
207.  929,  556 

242,  355.  569 
279,  237,  763 
284,366,811 

243.  539,  140 
290,  920,  288 
281,  806.  984 
278,  984,  551 
327,  324.  854 
335.  087,  691 
334.  379,  563 
405,  241,  095 
610, 404,  307 
927,713.414 
007, 680,  052 
792, 220, 835 
823,788,417 
694,  310, 235 
709,  074, 010 
781.724,062 
735.  986,  097 
753,  445,  627 
786,  747,  687 
723,  803, 437 
780,  906,  264 
744,691.068 
717,217.277 
595, 820.  720 
507,915,913 
448, 973, 131 
457,  968,  505 
483.  878,  883 
513,  939.  237 
508.  296,  375 
544,  759,  493 


$1,  482,  528,  825 
1,511,798,510 
1,544,211,164 
1,544,812,404 
1,572,453,335 
1,  599,  315,  431 
1,657,339,629 
1,  637,  061,  469 
1,692,428,137 
1,712,019.845 
1,  739,  288,  534 
1.775.500.109 
1,800,586,323 
1.792,233.493 

1.  848.  541,  861 

2.  083.  027, 974 
2,  449,  650. 206 
2.571.617.175 
2.  365, 882.  382 
2.  430. 646, 963 
2.  339. 105.  310 
2.  340. 653.  216 
2.  420.  882,  704 
2,414, 194,  €66 
2,  446,  643,  331 
2,  454, 139,  185 
2.  433,  583. 169 
2,  442.  030.  233 
2.  286, 183,  656 
2.394,644,611 
2.  279. 802, 813 
2.  168.  732,  222 
2, 102, 896.  880 
2.  084, 112,  287 
1,822.401,742 
1.863,976,619 
1. 918,  729,  289 
1,711,279,006 


Data  are  as  shown  on  books  at  the  end  of  each  year.    Data  for  1901  are  .partially  estimated. 
Fixed  assets  include  good  will  and  other  intangible  items,  as  well  as  tangible  property. 
All  property  values  are  "net,"  after  the  deduction  cf  rererves  for  Jepletien,  depreciati'yi.,etc. 
Current  assetsiQcJade  a  relatively^mall  amount  of  other  a-s.'^te,  e.  g  ,  mining  royaltiis,  deferred  charges, 
to.    Intel -company  profit  in  inventories-has  been  eliminated  froW  ctnrent  assets. 


13746       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Assets — 1938  compared  with  1901 — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


1901  (April  1st) 


1938  (December 
31st) 


Land,  Buildings,  Equipment,  etc. 

Intangibles 

Current  Assets 


$545,500,0C0  $1,166,519,512 

749, 207, 806  1 

.'j4,  694, 676  544,759,493 


$1,489,402,482  $1,711,279,006 


Allocation  of  fixed  assets  in  1901,  as  between  land,  buildings,  equipment,  etc.,  and  intangibles,  is  that  of 
U.  S.  Bureau  of  Corporations  made  in  1911. 


ASSETS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 


While  fixed  assets  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  ce  now  carried  on  the  books 
at  less  than  the  value  of  fixed  assets  at  the  time  of  the  organization  in  1 90 1 , 
the  Corporation's  physical  plant  is  much  greater  today.  This  largely  results 
from  two  causes: 

(1)  The  elimination  from  time  to  time  of  all  intangible  values.  When  the 
Corporation  was  formed,  various  going  businesses  were  acquired  at  prices 
in  excess  of  the  value  of  their  tangible  property,  resulting  in  intangibly 
assets  of  about  $750,CX)0,000  (as  later  determined  by  the  U.  S.  Bureau  of 
Corpo.'atlons),  representing  the  good-will  or  earning  power  of  these  busi- 
nesses. While  originally  of  real  value,  it  has  been  deemed  prudent  to  write- 
down from  time  to  time  the  value  of  all  such  intangible  items,  gogd-wlll  now 
being  valued  at  $1.00. 

(2)  The  reserve  for  obsolescence  and  depreciation  was  Increased  to  the 
extent  of  $270,000,000  in  1935,  principally  because  of  improvements  in 
manufacturing  methods  v/hich  made  existing  facilities  of  older  design  less 
valuable. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13747 


7\SSETS  -  1938  COMPARED  WITH  1901 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
MILLIONS  OF  DOLLARS 


CURRENT  ASSETS 


1,600 


1,200 


1 


WND,  BUILDINGS, 

EQUIPMENT,  ETC 


1901 

(Apr.  1st) 


ASSETS  OF  THE  CORPORATION  ARE  CONSERVATIVELY  VALUED 

1.  Values  of  property  are  based  on  reports  of 
Departments  of  U.  S.  Government 

2.  Property  was  certified  to  be  conservatively 

valued  by  independent  engineers  as  of  Dec.  31,  1937 

3.  Intangible  values  have  been  written  down  to  $  1 


The  amount  of  intangibles  originally  included  in  the  property  account  of 
U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  at  its  organization  on  April  1 ,  1 901  represented  the 
good  will  or  earning  power  of  the  various  going  businesses,  which  were  con- 
solidated to  form  the  Corporation,  over  and  above  the  value  of  their 
tangible  assets.  This  amount  has  been  written  off  from  time  to  time  and 
was  finally  reduced  to  $1.00  in  1938. 

Of  the  total  of  nearly  $750,000,000  of  intangibles,  $182,000,000  was 
written  off  against  current  earnings,  $285,000,000  against  capital  surplus, 
and  the  remainder  against  earned  surplus. 


13748  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Capital,  surplus  and  liabilities — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidictries 


Year 

Preferred 
Stock 

Common 
Stock 

Surplus  and 
Reserves 

Funded  Debt 

Current  Li- 
abilities 

Total 

$510,  205,  743 
510,281,100 
360,  281,' 100 
360,  281, 100 
360,  281,  100 
360,  281,  100 
360,  281, 100 
360,281,100 
360.281,100 
360,281,100 
360,  281, 100 
360,281,100 
360,  281, ICO 
360,  281, 100 
360,281,100 
360,281,100 
360.  281,  100 
360,281,100 
360,281,100 
360,  281, 100 
360,  281, 100 
360,281,100 
360, 281, 100 
360,  281, 100 
360,  281, 100 
360,  281, 100 
360,  281, 100 
360,  281, 100 
360,  281, 108 
360,  281,  100 
360.  281, 100 
360,281,100 
360,281,100 
360,281,100 
360,  281, 100 
360,  281, 100 
360,  281, 100 
360,  281, 100 

$508,  227,  394 
.508,  302,  500 
508,  302,  500 
508,  302,  ,500 
508,  302,  500 
,508,  302,  500 
,508.  302,  500 
,508,  302,  500 
508,  302,  500 
508,  302,  500 
,508,  302,  500 
.508,  302,  500 
508,  302,  500 
508,  3t  .2,  500 
508,  302,  500 
508,  302,  500 
508,  302,  500 
508,  302,  500 
508, 302,  500 
508, 302,  500 
508,  302,  500 
508,302.500 
508,  302,  500 
508,  302,  500 
508,  302,  500 
.508,  30?,  500 
711,  623,  500 
711,623,500 
813,284,000 
868,  743,  500 
870,  325,  200 
870,  325,  200 
870,  325,  200 
870.325,200 
870,  325,  200 
870,  325,  200 
870,  325,  200 
652,  743,  900 

$29,  550, 140 
■  72,827,866 
61,956,410 
60,  048, 347 
89,  595,  628 
120,648,046 
137,351,182 
127,412,522 
152,932,904 
190,531.446 
196,  817,  873 
201,966,918 
235,  872,  934 
220,  679, 690 
271,071,558 
491,698.022 
617,577,414 
687,  607,  2,53 
738,017,793 
818,406,123 
813,758.392 
801,660,015 
8.56,910,754 
882,163,4.30 
922, 177,  402 
944, 859,  235 
752,  226.  629 
777,180,077 
848,811,007 
925, 487,  442 
864,  810,  665 
764,  707,  681 
706,  870,  895 
679,  719,  257 
408,023,691 
411,969,078 
445,  083,  957 
370, 143,  288 

$380,  365,  8.30 
370.  560.  792 
574, 130,  514 
576,  342,  203 
573,  506,  549 
566,411,776 
606,341,022 
598,  033,  493 
609,  766,  907 
600,070,012 
622,251,002 
644,  .5.38,  723 
637, 552,  728 
661,102,374 
644, 0,52,  373 
629,803,916 
623,  Oo7,  609 
617,644,840 
602,  209,  725 
586,812,045 
572,514,762 
571,756,017 
557,  985,  323 
540,488,518 
537, 964,  166 
519,  574,  424 
500,  529,  307 
480,  429,  556 
134,788,423 
123,  054,  594 
119,063,247 
114,921,210 
110,398,829 
117,496,363 
114,240,603 
117,843,431 
125,707,961 
248, 849, 388 

$.54, 179,  718 
49,826,2.52 
39,  540,  640 

39,  838,  2.54 

40,  767,  5.58 
43,  672, 009 
45, 063, 825 
43.031,854 
61,144,726 
52,834,787 
51,636,059 
60,410,868 
58,577,061 
41,867,829 
64, 8,34, 330 
92, 942,  436 

340,351,583 
397,781,482 
157,071,264 
156,  745, 195 
84,  248,  556 
98,  753,  584 
137,403,027 
122,9.59,118 
116,918,163 
121,121,926 
108,922,633 
112,516,000 
129,019,125 
116,977,975 
6.5,  322, 601 
48,  497,  031 
55,020,856 
56,  290,  367 
69,531,148 
103,  557,  710 
117,331,071 
79,  261,  330 

$1,  482,  528.  825 

1902. 

1903 

1,. 511,  798,  510 
1,544,211.164 

1904 

1  544  812  404 

1905 

1.572,453,335 

1906 

1,599,315,431 

1907 

1,657,339,629 

1908 

1909 

1,6.37,061,469 
1,692.428,137 

1,739,288,534 

1,775,500,109 

1,800,586,323 

1,792,233,493 

1915 

1,848,541,861 

1916 

2,083,027,974 

1917 

2,  449, 550,  206 

1918 

2,571,617,175 

1919 

2, 365, 882,  382 

1920 

2, 430,  546, 963 

1921 

2,  339, 105,  310 

2,  340,  653,  216 

2, 420,  882,  704 

2,414,194,666 

2, 445,  643, 331 

1926 — . 

1927 

1928 

2,  454, 139, 185 
2, 433,  583, 169 
2, 442,  030,  233 

1929 

2,  286,  183,  655 

1930 

1931 

2,394,544,611 
2,279,802,813 

1932 

2, 158,  732.  222 

2,102,896,880 

2,084.112,287 

1,  822,  401,  742 

1936.. 

1,  863,  976,  519 

1937 

1,918,729,289 
1,711,279,006 

1938 

Data  are  as  shown  on  books  at  the  end  of  each  year.    Data  for  1901  are  partially  estimated. 
Premiums  on  common  stock  sold  are  included  with  surplus. 
Surplus  is  exclusive  of  inter-Company  profit  in  inventories. 

Reserves  do  not  include  depreciation,  depletion  and  amortization  reserves,  which  are  applied  to  the  credit 
of  gross  property  investment. 
Purchase  money  obligations  and  minority  interest  are  included  with  funded  debt. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13749 


CAPITAL,  SURPLUS  AND  LIABILITIES 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 


THE  CORPORATION  HAS  A  RELATIVELY  SMALL  INDEBTEDNESS 


U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  has  a  sound  financial  structure,  with  a  relatively 
small  amount  of  liabilities  and  a  comparatively  large  amount  of  surplus 
and  reserves,  and  capital  stock.  Present  capitalization  is  represented 
entirely  by  tangible  assets. 

A  large  part  of  the  funded  debt  was  retired  In  1929,  resulting  in  substantial 
reduction  In  fixed  charges  further  fortifying  the  Corporation  against 
business  depressions. 

The  decrease  in  surplus  and  reserves  since  1930  reflects  depression  period 
losses,  the  increase  in  reserve  for  obsolescence  and  depreciation  in  1935, 
and  the  write-down  to  $  1 .00  of  the  intangibles  remaining  In  1938. 
The  Increase  In  common  stock  In  1927  was  the  result  of  a  40%  stock  divi- 
dend, that  In  1929  was  due  to  the  sale  of  additional  common  stock  for 
cash,  and  that  in  1930  was  in  connection  with  property  acquisitions,  viz.. 
Atlas  Portland  Cement  Company,  Oil  Well  Supply  Company  and  Colum- 
bia Steel  Corporation;  the  decrease  in  1938  was  due  to  the  change  in  the 
common  stock  from  $  1 00  par  value  to  no  par  value,  with  a  stated  capital  of 
$75  per  share. 


13750  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Earnings  and  cash  dividends — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Year 

Earnings 
(After  In- 
terest) 

Earnings 
(After  Com- 
mon and 
Preferred 
Dividends 

Preferred 
Dividends 

Common 
Dividends 

Total  Cash 
Dividends 

$61,807,993 
90,306,525 
5.5,416,653 
30,  267,  529 
68,  585,  492 
98.  128,  587 
114,565,564 
45,  728,  714 
79, 073,  695 
87,  407, 185 
55,  300,  297 
.54,  240, 049 
81,  216,  986 
23, 496,  768 
75,833,832 
271,531,731 
224,  219,  564 
125,317,377 
76.  794,  582 
109,  694,  228 
36,  617, 017 
39, 653,  455 
1(8,707,065 
85, 067, 192 
90, 602,  653 
116,667,405 
57. 896, 836 
114,173,775 
197,  ,592, 060 
;04.421,571 
13,038,142 
'  71, 175,  705 
'  36,  501, 123 
■  21,  667,  780 
1, 146,  708 
50,  583, 356 
94.  944,  358 
'  7,  717,  454 

$19,828,824 

34,253,657 

12,304,917 

5,047,852 

43,365,815 

62,  742,  860 

69,179.837 

10,  342,  987 

33,521,918 

36,  772,  383 

4,  665,  495 

3, 605,  247 

30, 582, 184 

1  16, 971, 984 

44,  260,  374 

201,835,585 

107,505,437 

28, 935, 350 

26, 159,  780 

59,059,426 

'  14,017,785 

'  10,  981, 347 

54,  259, 994 
24,  266, 340 
29,801,801 

55,  866,  553 
12,893,514 
39, 140,  453 

108,  523,  343 
18,836,097 
'  49, 165,  485 
'91,891,868 
'  43,  706,  745 
■  28,  873.  402 
1  6, 058,  914 
144,002 
27,  695,  427 
1  32,  937, 131 

$26,  752,  539 
35, 720, 178 
30,  404, 173 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,219,677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
2,5,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219.  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219.  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 

25,  219,  677 
25, 219, 677 

26,  219,  677 
25,  219,  677 
25,2il9,677 
25,  219,  677 
20,  716, 163 

7,  205,  622 
7,  205, 622 
7,  205,  622 
50.  439.  354 
58,  545,  679 
25,  219,  677 

$15,  226, 630 
20, 332,  690 
12, 707, 663 

$41, 979, 169 
56,052,868 
43,111,736 

1902    - 

1903 

1904.    .   

1905 -- - 

1906 

10, 166,  050 
10, 166,  050 
10,166,050 
20,  332, 100 
25,415,125 
25,  415, 125 
25,  415, 125 
25,  415, 125 
15,  249,  075 
6,  353,  781 
44,  476, 469 
91, 494, 450 
71, 162, 350 
25,  415, 125 
25,  415,  125 
25,415,125 
25,415,125 
29,  227,  334 
35,  581, 175 
35,681,175 
35,  581, 175 
49, 813, 645 
49, 813,  645 
63,  849,  040 
60,  365,  797 
36, 983, 950 

35,  385,  727 
35  385  727 

1907 

1908 

35  385  727 

1909 

45  651  777 

1910 

50  634  802 

1912 - 

50,  634,  802 

1917...     

1918 

1919 

1920 

50  634  802 

1921 

50  634  802 

1922 

50  634  802 

1923 

54  447  071 

1924 

60,800  852 

1925 

60,  800  852 

1926 

60,800  852 

1927                

1928 

1929 

1930 -.- 

1931 

1932 

89,  068,  717 
85,  585,  474 
62.  203,  627 
20,  716, 163 

1933 

7  205  622 

1934 

7  205  622 

1935 

7,205  622 

1936 

50,439,354 

1937.-.- 

8, 703, 252 

67,  248, 931 



Earnings  are  after  all  charges,  Including  interest,  bond  premium  and  discount,  all  taxes,  and  additions  to 
bond  sinking  funds  which  were  later  applied  to  amortization  of  intangibles. 

Earnings  would  be  slightly  lower  if  the  special  addition  to  depreciation  reserve  of  $270,000,000  in  1935 
could  be  accurately  apportioned  over  prior  years. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13751 


EARNINGS  AND  CASH  DIVIDENDS 

UNITED  STATES  STEEL  [1    CORPORATION    AND    SUBSIDIARIES 


Cn      0>      CT>      Ci 


1    \  COMMON 

1    Idivdenos 

t    t    ft    +-'l 

A 

PREFERRED                                             \                       ..     /                \ 
>VDVIDENDS                                 /           i                 /••■• 

\ 

'  ^ ,>i__i«i^._:: 

\ 

-'^       /      ^  * 

:l7t::::i:;:;::::::::::: 

r-^A 

a^      CT>      CTi      CT^ 


•5j-u3ooo<Nj«e-tDooo 


U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  earnings  and  cash  dividends  on  the  common  stock 
have  fluctuated  greatly  since  1901. 

Since  1930,  earnings  have  been  insufficient  to  cover  preferied  dividend 
requirements  in  all  but  two  years.  Less  than  the  full  amount  of  the  preferred 
dividend  was  paid  in  each  of  the  years  1932-1935.  inclusive,  and  the 
accumulated  arrearages  were  paid  off  from  the  earnings  of  1936  and  1937 
The  common  stock  has  received  no  dividend  since  1931,  with  the  exception 
of  $1.00  per  share  paid  in  1937. 


13752  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Earnings    and   cash    dividends    per   share    of   common   slock — United   Slates  Steel 
Corporation 


Year 

Earnings 

per  Share 

of  Common 

Stock 

Cash  Divi- 
dends per 
Share  of 
Common 
Stock 

Year 

Earnings 

per  Share 

of  Common 

Stock 

Cash  Divi- 
dends per 
Share  of 
Common 
Stock 

1901 

$6.90 
10.74 

4.92 
.99 

8.53 
14.34 
15.61 

4.03 
10.59 
12.23 

5.92 

5.71 
11.02 

1.34 

9.96 
48.46 
39.15 
19.69 
10.15 

$3.00 
4.00 
2.50 

1920                                ...   - 

$16. 62 
2.24 
2.84 
16.42 
11.77 
12,86 
17.99 
10.28 
12.50 
22.61 
9.42 
1  1.40 
1  11.08 
1  7.09 
"  5.  39 
"  2.77 
2.91 
8.01 
13.78 

$5.00 

1902 

1921 

5.00 

lOOSf'' 

1922                  

5.00 

1904 

1923... 

1924             -. 

5.75 

1905 

7.(X) 

1906 

2.00 
2.09 
2.00 
4.00 
5.00 
5.00 
5.00 
5.00 
3.iX) 
1.25 
8.75 
18.00 
14.00 
5.00 

1925            .- 

7.0O 

1907 

1926 

7.00 

1908 

1927         • 

7.00 

1909 

1928         

7.00 

8.00 

7.00 

4.25 

1932  ..-- 

1933     -- 

1934 

19.35 

1936 

1937 

1.00 

1938 

I  Indicates  loss. 

Earnings  data  used  are  the  consolidated  earnings  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries  after  all 
charges,  including  interest,  bond  premium  and  discount,  all  taxes,  and  additions  to  bond  sinking  funds 
which  were  later  applied  to  amortization  of  intangibles. 

Earnings  would  be  slightly  lower  if  the  special  addition,  to  depreciation  reserve  of  5270,000,000  in  1935  could 
be  accurately  apportioned  over  prior  years. 

Calculation  of  earnings  per  share  is  based  upon  average  of  common  shares  outstanding  at  beginning  and 
end  of  year;  earnings  are  after  preferred  dividend  requirement,  regardless  of  amount  paid. 


Ratio  of  earnings  to  net  assets — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Year 

Earnings 
(Before 
Interest) 

Net  Assets  (As- 
sets less  Cur- 
rent Liabilities) 

Ratio  of 
Earnings  to 
Net  Assets 
(Percent) 

1920            

$139, 043,  581 
65. 109, 283 
68, 020,  445 
136,718,703 
112,377,701 
117,711,771 
143,425,343 
113,960,340 
139,919,784 
212,536,930 
110,061,667 
18,  507,  766 

>  65,  862.  244 

>  31,  336,  670 
I  16,616,728 

6, 106,  488 

55,  501,  787 

100,085,446 

644, 874 

$2,273,801,768 
2,  254,  8.56, 754 
2,241,899,632 
2,283,479,677 
2,  291,  235,  548 
2,328,72.M68 
2.333,017,257 
2,  324,  660,  536 
2.  3'29,  514.  233 
2,  157. 164,  530 
2.  277,  566.  636 
2.  214.  480.  212 
2,110.235,191 
2. 047.  876,  024 
2.027,821,920 
1.752,870,594 
1,760,418,809 
1.801,398.218 
1,632,017,676 

6.12 

1921    - 

2.89 

1922 - - 

3.03 

1923 

5.99 

1924 

4.90 

1925 

5.05 

1926 

6.15 

1927 

4.90 

1928 

6.01 

1929 

9.85 

1930                                                                                      

4.83 

1931                                                                                

0.84 

1932                                                    

'  3.12 

'  1.53 

■0.82 

0.35 

3.15 

1937         

6.56 

1938 - - 

0.03 

I  Indicates  loss. 

Earnings  are  before  interest  but  after  all  other 


including  all  taxes. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13753 


RATIO  OF  EARNINGS  TO  NET  ASSETS 

(EARNINGS  BEFORE  INTEREST  -   TOTAL  ASSETS  LESS  CURRENT  LIABILITIES) 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

12 

12 

10 

10 

> 

8 

/ 

\ 

8 

/ 

\ 

6 

f 

\ 

6 

t- 

V 

/ 

s 

__ 

s 

/ 

t- 

z 

4 

\ 

/ 

1 

/ 

4        5 

lU 

> 

/ 

\ 

... 

.    . 

/ 

.  , 

'-' 

\ 

1920-1938 

1 

a: 

? 

3  4"; 

2        0^ 

'^ 

0 

^ 

/ 

a. 
0 

\ 

^ 

-2 

\ 

^ 

-2 

\ 

/ 

-4 

-4 

Since  1920,  the  roMo  of  earnings  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  to  the  com, 
bined  investment  of  stockholders  and  bondholders  has  averaged  approxi- 
mately 3.4%.  For  the  past  ten  years  the  ratio  has  been  slightly  less 
than  2%. 


13754  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Ratio  of  earnings  to  net  assets —  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Earnines  Net  Assets  (As- 
(Before  sets  less  Cur- 
Interest)      !  rent  Liabilities) 


Ratio  of 
Earnings  to 
Net  Assets 

(Percent) 


1004 
1905 
1906 
1907 
1908 
1909 
1910 
1911. 
1912 
1913 
1914 
1915 
1916 
1917. 
1918. 
1919 
1920. 
1921. 
1922. 
1923 
1924 
1925. 
1926. 
1927. 
1928. 
1929. 
1930. 
1931. 
1932. 
1933. 
1934. 
1:^35. 
19b6. 
1937 


$1,461,972, 
1,504,670, 
1,  504, 974, 
1,  531,  685, 
1,  565,  643, 
1,612,275, 
1,594,029, 
1,631,283, 
1,  659,  185. 
1,687,652, 
1,715,089, 
1,  742, 0O9. 
1,  750,  365. 
1,  783,  707. 

1,  990, 085, 

2,  100, 198. 
2,  173.  835, 
2,208,811, 
2.273,801, 
2. 254, 856, 
2,241,899, 
2,  283,  479, 
2,291,23,'), 
2.  328.  725. 
2,333,017, 
2.  324.  660. 
2,  329, 614, 
2, 157, 164, 
2,  277.  566, 
2.214.  iSO, 
2,110,235, 
2. 047.  876. 
2,027,821, 
1,  752,  870, 
1,760,418, 
1, 801,  398, 
1,632,017, 


7.63 
5,39 
4.01 
6.42 
8,20 
8,31 
4,83 
6  78 
7,11 
5.12 
5,06 
6,57 
3.24 
6.09 
15.25 
12.10 
7.74 
4.84 
6.12 

3!  03 
5.99 
4.90 
5.05 
6,15 
4.90 
6.01 
9,85 
4,83 
0,84 
'3.12 
1  1.53 
'0.82 
0.35 
3,15 
5,56 
0,03 


Indicates  loss. 
Earnings  are  before  interest  but  after  all  other  charges,  including  all  taxes. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  FOWEU 


13755 


RATIO  OF  EARNINGS  TO  NET  ASSETS 

(EARNINGS  BEFORE  INTEREST  -  TOTAL  ASSETS  LESS  CURRENT  LIABILITIES) 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

u 

I           \  - 

1   ,    \    '^'L-v  ,,      ^ 

^  ..     .  ^2  -.ll.2^f.\.j Yd 

L „  js  .2  s<? - :.  -.  "-AyESi?  l;  ^.. .    ^ 

S       3           ^^                        V 

GX\_  _  ir.^'/    3  s 

V  /  ^ 

t---:::& ::.::! 

-fi 

-6 

900 
902 
904 
906 
908 
910 
912 
914 
916 
918 

Sines  organlza+ron,  the  ratio  of  earnings  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  to 
the  combined  investment  of  stockholders  and  bondholders  has  averaged 
approximately  5.1%;  since  1920,  the  ratio  has  been  about  3.4%;  and  for 
the  past  ten  years  the  ratio  has  been  slightly  less  than  2%,. 


Distribution  of  the  sales  dollar 


1929-1938  inclusive- 
subsidiaries 


-U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and 


Classification 

Dollar 
Amount 

Per  Cent 
of  Sales 

Payroll  (Wages  and  Salaries) 

$2, 804, 198, 490 
2,379,954,228 
512, 132, 759 
464,685,657 
64,885,182 
252, 196, 770 
72, 467, 364 

42.8 

Goods  and  Services  Purchased  from  Others 

36.4 

Depreciation  and  Depletion 

7.8 

Taxes  (Federal,  State  and  Local) 

7.  1 

Bond  Interest  (Including  Premium  and  DLscount) 

1.0 

Dividends  on  Preferred  Stock 

3  8 

Available  for  Dividends  on  Common  Stock 

1.  1 

Sales  and  other  Revenues 

$6,  550, 500. 450 

100  0 

Payroll  represents, wages  and  salaries  paid  to  all  employees  of  all  companies.  The  relatively  small  con- 
struction payroll  has  been  excluded  as  constituting  capital  expenditures  subsequently  recoverable  through 
depreciation  charges. 

The  amount  available  for  dividends  on  common  stock  does  not  represent  the  total  amount  paid  but  only 
the  portion  provided  by  sales  and  revenues  during  the  period  covered. 

Sales  and  other  revenues  represent  the  total  amount  available  for  the  payment  of  all  expenses  and  other 
obligations.  In  eliminating  inter-company  business,  amounts  applicable  to  transportation  companies 
were  partially  estimated. 


124491— 41— pt.  26-  —12 


13756       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Distribution  of  sales  dollar — year  19S8 — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Payroll  (Waees  and  Salaries) c 

Goods  and  Services  Purchased  from  Others. 

Depreciation  and  Depletion.  

Taxes  (Federal,  State  and  Local). 

Available  to  Apply  on  Bond  Interest... 


$275.  364,  898 

237,454,811 

49,193.448 

48,  842, 131 

544, 874 


45.0 

38.9. 
8.0 
8.0 
0.1 


Sales  and  Other  Revenues. 


$611,400,162 


Payroll  represents  wages  and  salaries  paid  to  all  employees  of  all  companies.  The  relatively  small  con- 
struction payroll  has  been  excluded  as  constituting  capital  expenditures  subsequently  recoverable  through 
depreciation  charges. 

The  amount  available  to  apply  on  bond  interest  does  not  represent  the  total  amount  paid  but  only  the 
portion  provided  by  sales  and  revenues  during  the  period  covered. 

Sales  and  other  revenues  represent  the  total  amount  available  for  the  payment  of  all  expenses  and  other 
obligations.  In  elimfnating  inter-company  business,  amounts  applicable  to  transporta.  ion  companies 
were  partially  estimated. 


DISTRIBUTION  OF  THE  SALES  DOLLAR 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
1929-1938  INCLUSIVE 

AVAIUBLE  FOR  COMMON  DIVIDENDS  1 
PREFERRED  DIVIDENDS  3.8« 
BOND  INTEREST  1  0« 
TAXES  7 1« 

DEPRECIATION  AND  DEPLETION 


GOODS  AND  SERVICES 

PURCHASED  FROM  OTHERS 

36.4  C 


During  the  past  ten  years.  42.8^  of  every  dollar  of  sales  and  other 
revenues  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries  were  paid  to  enn- 
ployees  In  wages  and  salaries.  Despite  a  relatively  high  degree  of 
integration,  the  Corporation  spent  36.4{*  for  goods  and  services  pur- 
chased from  others,  e.  g.,  scrap,  non-ferrous  metals.  Inward  freight, 
electric  power,  tools,  lubrication,  etc.  Depreciation  of  plant  and  equip- 
ment amounted  to  LQif.  Taxes  absorbed  7.1^. 

There  remained  for  the  bondholders  and  stockholders  only  5.9^,  of  which 
1.0^  went  for  bond  interest,  3.8^  went  for  preferred  dividends  and  l.l^ 
were  available  for  dividends  on  the  common  stock. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13757 


DISTRIBUTION  OF  THE  SALES  DOLLAR 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
YEAR  1938 

AVAIWBLE  TO  APPLY  ON  BOND  INTEREST  0  1« 
TAXES 


GOODS  AND  SERVICES 

PURCHASED  FROM  OTHERS 

38.9( 


INCOME  WAS  INSUFFICIENT  TO  COVER  BONO  INTEREST  BV  $7,717,454,  THE  LOSS  FOR  THE  YEAR 


In  the  year  1938,  45.0^  out  of  every  dollar  of  sales  and  other  revenues  of 
U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries  were  paid  to  employees  in  wages 
and  salaries,  38.9^  were  absorbed  by  goods  and  services  purchased  from 
others,  8.0^  by  depreciation  of  plant  and  equipment,  and  8.0^  by  federal, 
state  and  local  ta»es. 

The  amount  remaining  was  insufficient  to  cover  bond  interest  by 
$7,717,454,  the  loss  for  the  year.  After  payment  of  preferred  dividends, 
the  loss  for  the  year  was  $32,937, 1 3  L 


13758  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Payroll  and  earnings  per  dollar  of  sales — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


1904 
1905 
1906 
1907 
1908 
1909 
1910 
1911 
1912 
1913 
1914 
1915. 
1916. 
1917. 
1918 
1919 
1920 
1921. 
1922. 
1923. 
1924. 
1925. 
1926 
1927 
1928. 
1929. 
1930. 
1931. 
1932. 
1933. 
1934. 
1935. 
1936. 
1937. 


Thousands  of  Dollars 


Payroll 


Sales  and 

Other 
Revenues 


422, 1S7 
39.^  275 
324,  682 
400,  382 
484,  535 
504,  749 
331,  S07 
442,506 
492,  574 
433,  036 
535,  490 
561,  745 
413.166 
524,  922 
903, 033 
1,276,358 
1.328,248 

l!  295,' 849 
725,  945 
809,  310 

'  920,'  742 
1,023,812 
1,087,165 
961,980 
1.010,952 


377. 179 
423.  201 
.544, 173 
791, 697 
1  028,751 
611,400 


Payroll  per 
Dollar 
of  Sales 


$0.  285 
.306 
.307 
.313 
.305 
.319 
.363 
.343 
.355 
.373 
.354 
.369 
.393 
.337 
.292 
.272 
.341 
.432 
.449 
.458 


Earnings 

per  Dollar 

of  Sales 


,107 


.113 
.181 
.124 
.024 
1.247 
1.097 
1.051 
.002 
.064 
.092 
1.013 


>  Indicates  loss 

Payroll  represents  total  wages  and  salaries  paid  to  all  employees  of  all  companies  and  includes  a  relaiivily 
small  amount  of  construction  payroll,  which  it  was  not  pos.<!ible  to  exclude  in  early  years. 

Earnines  are  after  all  charges,  including  interest,  bond  premium  and  discount,  all  taxes,  and  addition?  to 
bond  sinking  funds  which  were  later  applied  to  amortization  of  intangibles.  Earnings  after  interest  but 
before  additions  to  bond  sinking  funds  were  about  one  cent  more  per  dollar  of  sales  than  those  shown,  for 
the  years  lOOl-lCTS,  inclusive. 

Sales  and  other  revenues  represent  the  total  amount  available  for  the  payment  of  all  expenses  and  other 
oblieations.  In  eliminating  inter-company  business,  amounts  applicablejzi  transportation  companies  wen- 
partially  estimated. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13759 


PAYROLL  AND  EARNINGS  PER  DOLLAR  OF  SALES 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

^ 

/VkIa.''  /^^/^\  /     ^° 

__^/-'^^A        J 

-  '    1                m 

c/o 

EARNINGS       A                                                 ^ 

J»nER  INTEREST)  J^    \l                                                                     " 

^^tT"l"'"/l'"'° 

----     ~  "\~~y/~ 

X-A-          -10 

-20 

1//                         -20 

8gSg§2^2:22S 

922 

924 
926 
928 
330 
2.^ 
934 
936 
938 
940 

.  ^  ^                  ^ 

Ever  since  the  organization  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  in  1 90 1 ,  the  propor- 
tion of  the  sales  dollar  going  to  employees  in  the  form  of  wages  and  sal- 
aries has  had  an  upward  trend,  increasing  from  about  30#  in  1901  to  about 
45^  in  1938.  The  portion  remaining  as  earnings  available  for  dividends  to 
stoclcholders.  however,  has  declined,  even  more  than  the  portion  going  to 
employees  has  increased. 


13760 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Payments  lo  employees  and  to  investors  per  dollar  of  sales —  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 
and  subsidiaries 


Thousands  of  Dollars 


Payroll 


Interest 
and  Cash 
Dividends 


Sales  and 

Other 
Revenues 


Payroll  per 
Dollar  of 


Interest 

and 
Dividends 
per  Dollar 

of  Sales 


1906.. 
1006. 
1907. 
1908. 
1909. 
1910. 
1911. 
1912. 
1913. 
1914. 
1915. 
1916. 
1917. 
1918. 
1919. 
1920. 
1921. 


1924. 
1925. 
1926. 
1927. 
1928. 


120,528 
120,764 
99,778 
128, 053 
147, 766 
160,826 
120, 511 
151,663 
174,955 
,161,419 
189,  352 
207,206 
162,380 
176, 801 
263, 386 
347, 370 
452,664 
479,  548 
581, 557 
332,888 
322, 678 
469,  503 
442,  459 
456,  740 
467,  409 
430,  727 
413,  700 
420,073 
391,  271 
266,871 
133, 913 
163, 150 
210,  504 
251,  577 


77,354 
68,748 
55,311 
54,986 
64,787 
64,738 
66,650 
77,056 
81,  265 
81,  779 
83,204 
83,  936 
73,700 
64,327 
101,  739 
147,  704 
127,  041 
80,  779 
79, 984 
79,  127 
79,002 


88,111 
S7,  910 
87,  559 
101,097 
100,  779 
104,  014 
91,226 
67,  673 
26,030 
12,  370 
12,  257 
12, 165 
55,358 
72,390 
33,  482 


422, 187 

395,  275 

324,682 

409,382 

484,  535 

504,  749 

331,  807 

442,506 

492,  574 

433, 036 

535,490 

561,  745 

413,  166 

524,  922 

903,  033 

1,  276,  358 

1,  328,  248 

1, 109,  898 

1,  295,  849 

725, 945 

809,  310 

1,  093,  552 

920,  742 

1,023,812 

1,  087, 165 

961,  980 

1,  010,  952 

1,  094, 074 

840,  226 

551, 126 

288,  664 

377, 179 

423,201 

544, 173 

791,  697 

1, 028,  761 

611,400 


$0,285 
.306 
.307 
.313 
.305 
.319 
.363 
.343 
.355 
.373 
.354 


$0,183 
.174 
.170 
.134 
.134 
.128 
.201 
.174 
.165 


Payroll  represents  total  wages  and  salaries  paid  to  all  employees  of  all  companies  and  includes  a  relatively 
small  amount  of  construction  payroll,  which  it  was  not  possible  to  exclude  in  early  years. 

Interest  includes  bond  premium  and  discount. 

Sales  and  other  revenues  represent  the  total  amount  available  for  the  payment  of  all  expenses  and  other 
obligations.  In  eliminating  inter-company  business,  amounts  applicable  to  transportation  companios 
were  partially  estimated. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEIt 


13761 


PAYMENTS  TO  EMPLOYEES  AND  INVESTORS  PER  DOLU\R  OF  SALES 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

en 

^'°                  -.'zz"''\A^'yt'^\'    .. 

^    :;/-''\  / 

</5 

H      30        ?-■                                   \'        " 

O 

'°  wMrffc^ 

S 
0 

J?^              .^     M^                          in 

,0 _ .^ 

WTW  : 

900 
902 
904 
906 
908 
910 
912 
914 
916 
918 
920 

922 
924 
926 
928 
930 
932 
934 
1936 
938 
1940 

From  1902  to  1938,  payroll  payments  to  employees  have  absorbed  an 
increasing  proportion  of  the  sales  dollar  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and 
subsidiaries,  while  interest  and  cash  dividend  payments  to  investors  have 
absorbed  a  decreasing  proportion. 


Taxes  per  dollar  of  sales — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Total 
Taxes 

Sales  and 

Taxes  per 

lotal 
Taxes 

.Sales  and 

Taxes  per 

Year 

Other 

Dollar  lof 

Year 

Other 

Dollar  of 

Revenues 

Sales 

Revenues 

Sales 

1920. 

$68,820,598 

$1,  296,  849,  375 

$0. 053 

1930... 

$49,523,594 

$840,226,222 

$0. 069 

1921 

37, 683,  727 

725, 944,  864 

0.052 

1931 

34,247,632 

651, 126,  423 

0.062 

1922 _ 

35,  798, 450 

809, 309,  543 

0.044 

1932 

31,737,202 

288,  663,  837 

0.110 

1923 _ 

55,082,523 

1,093,551,939 

0.050 

1933 

31,709,993 

377,179,040 

0.084 

1924 

45, 276, 855 

920,  742, 443 

0.049 

1934 

35, 780, 385 

423,201,194 

0.085 

1925 

60,  923. 191 

1,023,811,883 

0.050 

1935. 

38,575,010 

544, 172,  546 

0.071 

1926 

52,  542,  237 

1,087,164,574 

0.048 

1936 

52,150,945 

791,696,719 

0.066 

1927 

46,755,461 

961,979,849 

0.049 

1937 

88, 048, 237 

1,028,760,629 

0.086 

1928. 

61,233,103 

1,010,952,092 

0.051 

1938 

48, 842, 131 

611,400,162 

0.080 

1929 

55,386,167 

1,094,073,678 

0.051 

Taxes  include  all  federal,  state  and  local  taxes  of  all  companies. 

Federal  tax  adjustments  made  retroactive  to  years  in  which  applicable;  distribution  of  adjustments  to 
years  1917-1920,  inclusive,  partly  estimated. 

Sales  and  other  revenues  represent  the  total  amount  available  for  the  payment  of  all  expenses  and  other 
obligations.  In  eliminating  inter-company  business,  amounts  applicable  to  transportation  companies  were 
partially  estimated. 


13762 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


TAXES  PER  DOLLAR  OF  SALES 

12 

U.J 

>.  SI 

EEL 

gORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

"^  1  1  M  1  1  1 

12 

10 
8 

- 

— 

— 

— 

-^ 

- 

\ 

- 

y. 

J 

^ 

10 
8 

/ 

\ 

/ 

trt 

/ 

•v 

1 

V- 

z       6 

6 

y 

' 

m 

4 

\ 

^ 

__ 

_ 

4 

o 

■ 

2 
0 

2 

0 

? 

3j^f^RSSlS?2Sg3S?5S^SS!SiS!^S^S 

a>CT>CT>oicn<j>ai<ncT>cncri(naia>cn     CTia^CT>aiaS<j> 

From  1920  through  1930,  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries  paid  out 
each  year  in  taxes  approximately  5('  out  of  every  dollar  of  revenue  from 
sales  and  other  sources.  In  1938  the  tax  collectors  took  about  8^  out  of 
every  dollar  of  revenue. 

The  decrease  In  taxes  per  dollar  of  sales  subsequent  to  1932  was  not  the 
result  of  a  decline  in  the  total  amount  of  taxes  paid,  which  increased  from 
$31,710,000  in  1933  to  $88,048,000  in  1937  and  $48,842,000  in  1938,  but 
was  due  to  such  taxes  being  apportioned  over  an  increased  amount  of 
sales. 


Toial   taxes  and  earnings   available  for  dividends 
subsidiaries 


U.   S.   Steel  Corporation  and 


Year 

Earnings 

Available  for 

Dividends 

Total  Ta.xes 

Year 

Earnings 
Available  for 
Dividends 

Total  Taxes 

1920 

$109,694,228 
36,617,017 
39,  653, 455 

108,  707, 065 
85, 067, 192 
iiO,  602,  053 

116.667.405 
.S7, 896,  836 

114,17.3,775 

197,  592, 060 

$68,820,598 
37, 683,  727 
35,  798, 450 
55, 082,  523 

45,  276,  855 
60,923,191 
52,  642,  237 

46.  755,  461 
51,233,103 
55,386,167 

1930 

1931 

1932 

1933. -. 

$104,421,571 

i:i,  0.38, 142 

171,175,705 

1  36,  501, 123 

1  21,  067,  780 

1,146,708 

51.  .583.  356 

91.944,358 

'7,717,454 

$49, 523,  594 

1921 

1922 

1923 

34,  247,  632 
31,737,202 
31,709,993 

35,  780, 385 

1925 

1926. . 
1927 

1935 

1936 

1937 

38,  575, 010 
52,150,945 
88, 048,  237 

1928 

1938 

48,842,131 

1929 

'  .'    urillcs  loss. 

1  aniinps  arc  after  nil  chiirpes,  including  interest,  bond'  premium  and  discount,  all  taxes,  and  additions 
t"  boii'l  •■■inking  funds  wliicli  were  later  applied  to  amortisation  of  intangibles. 

T*te    iiicluile  all  federal,  state  and  local  taxes  of  all  companies. 

pedejal  tax  udjusin:outs  made  retroaetivc  to  years  in  which  npplieat'!e;  distribution  of  adjustments  to 
years  l9i;-iU20,  inclusive,  partly  estimated. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  I'OWER 


13763 


T 

200 

160 

1     120 

o 

°       80 

u. 

O 

CO      40 

z 
o 

^        0 

z 

-40 
-80 

OTAL  TAXES  AND  EARNINGS  AVAILABLE  FOR  DIVIDENDS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

/ 

\ 

160 

120  < 
o 

80    ^ 

o 

40       w 
z 
o 

0     .;j 

z 

-40 
-80 

EARNINGS 

AVAILABLE  FO 

DIVIDENDS 

/ 

\ 

y 

/ 

\ 

/ 

N 

/ 

\ 

1 

I 

^ 

L 

'•«.. 

.^ 

_TA) 

ES 

^^ 

^ 

y1 

/ 

\ 

. 

"~ 

,^' 

i/ 

\ 

y 

/ 

\ 

/ 

1 

1921 
1922 
1923 
1924 
1925 
1926 
1927 
1928 
1929 
1930 
1931 
1932 
1933 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1938 
1939 

From  1 930  through  1938,  U.S.  Steel  Corporation's  total  tax  bill  amounted 
to  about  $410,615,000,  whereas  during  this  period  earnings  available  for 
dividends  to  stockholders  were  about  $  1 27,072,000.  Thus,  the  Corporation 
during  the  last  nine  years  has  paid  in  taxes  over  three  times  as  much  as  the 
earnings  available  for  dividends  to  stockholders. 


Assets,  earnings  and  taxes — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Item 

1902 

1937 

1938 

$1,511,798,510 
90. 306, 525 

2,391,466 

$1,918,729,289 
94,944,358 

42,882,565 
31,749,768 
13,415,904 

EarninRs  Available  for  Dividends 

Taxes: 

State  and  Local  (Excl.  Social  Security).. 

17,717,4.')4 

32,044,825 
5, 488, 091 

Social  Security 

11  309  215 

2,391,466 

88,048,237 

48,842,131 

1  Indicates  loss. 

Assets  are  as  shown  on  books  at  the  end  of  each  year,  including  intangibles. 
Earnings  are  after  all  charges,  including  interest,  bond  premium  and  discount, 
to  bond  sinking  funds  which  were  later  applied  to  amortization  of  intangibles. 
Taxes  include  all  federal,  state  and  local  ta.xes  of  all  companies. 


taxes,  and  additions 


13764 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  I'OWElt 


ASSETS,  EARNINGS  AND  TAXES 


U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
MILLIONS  OF  DOLLARS 

ASSETS 

•EARNINGS  A 

FOR  DIVIC 

1 

/AILABLE 
ENDS 

90 

75 

TAXES 

1 



SOCIAL 
SECURITY 

FEDERAL 
.EXCLSOCStO 

-45 
-30 

- 

1 

STATE       1  1 
AND  LOCAL  ■  ■ 

_           II 

1 

I                   §1    " 

1902 

1937 
1938  ■ 

c 

1902 

1937 
1938 

From  1902  to  1937-1938  (these  two  years  being  averaged),  assets  of  U.  S. 
Steel  Corporation  increased  20%,  earnings  available  for  dividends 
declined  51%  and  taxes  rose  2750%. 

In  this  comparison  the  year  1902  was  selected  because  it  was  the  first  full 
year  of  the  Corporation's  operation;  an  average  of  the  years  1937  and 
1938  was  used  because  operations  were  high  in  one  year  and  low  in  the 
other  year,  the  average  being  considered  representative  of  present  day 
conditions. 


State  and  local  taxes — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 

Year 

Amount 

Year 

Amount 

1902 

$2, 391, 466 
2, 972, 600 
3,  052, 967 

3,  646, 490 

4,  356, 126 

5,  383, 924 
5,  361, 160 
7,597,871 
8,078,585 
8,846,422 
9,117,678 

11,296,095 
11,433,763 
11,804.650 
14,390,155 
13.577,204 
17,501,453 
21.968,387 
30,581,138 

1921 

$29, 227, 488 

1903 

1922 

31,251,245 

1904    . 

37, 005, 965 

1905 

31,513,311 

1906 

35,  298, 993 

1907 

1926 

35,  266, 010 

1908 

1927 

34,  469,  585 

1909 

1928 

35. 8.54,  669 

1910 

1929 

37,617,085 

1911 

1930 

35, 954, 861 

1912 

1931                              

34, 145, 185 

1913 

31,0f>5,300 

30, 335. 893 

1916 

1934 -. 

31,255,688 

1916 

1935 

32, 433.  ?67 

1917 

1936 

35.  397,  155 

1918 

1937                                        .... 

42, 882,  565 

1919  . 

1938                

32,  044, 825 

1920 

Data  exclude  social  security  taxes. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13765 


STATE  AND  LOCAL  TAXES 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 


ml 


anmi 


~  40 

—  35 
30 

-  25 

-  20 
--  15 

—  10 

—  5 

—  0 


State  and  local  taxes  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  increased  steadily  from 
^bout  $2,400,000  in  1902  to  approximately  $  I  3,500,000  In  1917.  Between 
1917  and  1920,  these  taxes  more  than  doubled,  although  the  Corpora- 
tion's Ingot  dapaclty  increased  less  than  1 .57o  and  tts  investment  In  prop- 
erty account  only  aisout  5%  during  this  period.  From  192  I  through  1938, 
state  and  local  taxes  varied  between  $29,000,000  and  $43,000,000,  the 
variation  being  largely  due  to  differences  in  volume  of  operations.  How- 
ever, even  In  1932.  the  year  of  lowest  operations,  these  taxes  amounted 
to  over  $30,000,000. 

The  great  Increase  In  state  and  local  taxes  after  1917  was  not  the  result  of 
a  corresponding  increase  in  taxable  property,  but  was  largely  caused  by 
increased  assessments  and  tax  rates,  state  and  local. 

Taxes — JJ.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


State  and  Local 

(Excl.  Social 

Security) 


Federal  (Excl. 
Social  Security) 


1922 
1923 
1924 
1925 
1926 
1927 
1928 
1929 
1930 
1931 
1932 
1933 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1938 


456,  239 
547,  205 
076,  558 
763,  544 
624, 198 
276,  227 
28.5,876 
378,  434 
769, 082 
568, 733 
102,  447 
671,  902 
374, 100 
524,  097 
141,643 
416,  670 
749,  768 
488,  091 


$3,  337,  120 
13,415,904 
11,  309,  215 


$37,  683,  727 
35,  798,  450 
55, 082,  523 

45,  276, 855 
50, 923, 191 
52,  542,  237 

46,  755,  461 
51,  233, 103 
55, 380, 167 
49,  523,  694 

34,  247,  632 
31,  737,  202 
31,709,993 

35,  780,  385 
38,57.5,010 
52, 150,  945 
88, 048,  237 
48, 842, 131 


Taxes  include  all  federal,  state  and  local  ta.\es  of  all  companies. 

Federal  tax  adjustments  made  retroactive  to  years  in  which  applicable;  distribution  of  adiustments  to 
years  1917-1920,  inclusive,  partly 


13766 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


TAXES 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 


SOCIAL 
SEClffilTY 

~(f£OtRAL- 
AND  ST«TEl 


i 


n 


^ 


m 


.  m 


40 
30 
20 
10 


The  heavy  burden  to  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  of  state  and  local  taxes  is 
ever  present,  whether  the  Corporation  is  operating  at  a  profit  or  a  loss. 

While  federal  taxes,  excluding  social  security  taxes,  are  less  In  years  of  tow 
operations  because  of  lower  income  taxes,  the  amount  of  federal  taxes  now 
paid  in  a  prosperous  year  is  much  greater  than  formerly.  Federal  taxes  in 
1937  were  about  $31,750,000  as  contrasted  with  about  $17,769,000  in 
1929,  an  increase  of'nearjy  80%,  despite  the  fact  that  production  in  193  7 
did  not  reach  the  level  of  1929. 

Social  security  taxes  now  add  an  additional  $10,000,000  to  $15,000,000 
annually  to  the  Corporation's  tax  bill. 

The  Corporation  paid  nearly  $50,000,000  in  taxes  in  1938,  despite  the  fact 
that  a  deficit,  after  interest,  of  nearly  $8,000,000  was  incurred. 


,  Taxes  paid  in  1937  and  19S8—U 

S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 

Item 

J937 

1938 

1937-38  Average 

$88,048,2.37 

261,  293 

13,  579,  086 

$1,028,760,629 

8,  703,  2.52 

$336.97 

$0.40 

$8.56 

$10.  12 

$48,  842,  131 

202,108 

7, 159,  543 

$611,400,162 

8,  703,  252 

$241.  66 

$6.70 

$7.99 

$5.61 

$68,  445, 184 

231,700 

Tons  of  Iron  and  Steel  Shipped 

10,  369,  664 

Sales  and  Other  Revenues 

$820,080,390 

Shares  of  Common  Stock 

8,  703,  252 

$295.  40 

$6.50 

$8.35 

Taxes  Per  Share  of  Common  Stock 

$7.86 

Taxes  include  all  federal,  state  and  local  taxes  of  all  companies. 

Iron  and  steel  shipped  includes  rolled  and  finished  steel  products,  pig  iron,  ferro-manganese  and  ing  .is. 

Sales  and  other  revenues  represent  the  total  amount  available  for  the  payment  of  all  expenses  and  other 
obligations.  In  eliminating  inter-company  business,  amounts  applicable  to  transportation  companies 
were  partially  estimated. 

In  calculating  amount  of  taxes  per  ton  of  steel  shipped,  taxes  of  cement  manufacturing  subsidiaries, 
amounting  to  $1,142,634  and  $901,744  in  1937  and  1938,  respectively,  were  eliminated:  taxes  of  certain  com- 
panies, the  operations  of  which  are  not  entirely  ■  lated  to  the  production,  sale  and  distribution  of  steeJ, 
were  included  in  full  because  satisfactory  alloca        was  not  possible. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13767 


U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries  paid  $136,890,368  in  taxes  during 
1937  and  1938 

This  is  equivalent  to  an  average  cost  per  year  of: 

$295.40  per  employee, 

$6.50  per  ton  of  iron  and  steel  shipped 

$8.35  per  $100  of  sales, 

$7.86  per  share  of  common  stock. 

An  average  of  the  years  1937  and  1938  was  used  because  operations  were 
high  in  one  year  and  low  in  the  other  year,  the  average  being  considered 
representative  of  present  day  conditions. 


Average  assets,  annual  sales  and  earnings — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidi- 
aries— 1929-1938  inclusive 


Year 

Total  Assets 

Sales  and  Other 
Revenues 

Enmines 

1929 .  

1930— 

1931 

It::;:::;::;:::.:. :;.;;:; :::;:::::::;:::::;::;:;:: 

1934.. 

$2,286,183,655 
2,394,544,611 
2, 279, 802, 813 
2, 158, 732, 222 
2,102,896,880 
2,084,112,287 
1,822,401,742 
1,863,976,619 
1,918,729,289 
1,711,279,008 
2,062,265,902 

$1,094,073,678 
840,  226,  222 
551,  126,  423 
288, 663, 837 
377, 179, 040 
423,  201, 194 
644, 172,  646 
791, 696,  719 
1,028,760,629 
611, 400, 162 
655,050,045 

$212,536,930 
■110,061,667 
18,  ')07, 766 
1  65, 862,  244 
1  31, 336, 670 
1  16,  616,  728 

IMS":              - 

1936 _. 

1937 

65,  601, 787 

W38.... 

<  Indicates  loss. 

Total  assets  are  as  shown  on  books  at  the  end  of  each  year,  including  intangibles. 

Sales  and  other  revenues  represent  the  total  amount  available  for  the  payment  of  all  expenses  and  other 
obligations.  In  eliminating  inter-company  business,  amounts  applicable  to  transportation  companies  were 
partially  estimated. 

Earnings  are  before  interest  but  after  all  other  charges,  including  all  taxes. 


13768 


(CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  rOWKK 


AVERAGE  ASSETS,  ANNUAL  SALES  AND  EARNINGS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
1929-1938  INCLUSIVE 

MILLIONS  OF  DOLLARS 
500  1,000  1,500 


ASSETS 


SALES 


EARNINGS 


A  HUGE  INVESTMENT  IN  J^ELATION  TO  SALES  IS  CHARACTERISTIC  OF  THE  STEEL 
BUSINESS.  EARNINGS  WERE  5.9%  OF  SALES  BUT  ONLY  1.9%  OF  ASSETS. 


The  integrated  production  of  steel  requires  a  heavy  investnnent  in  iron 
ore  and  coal  nnines.  transportation  facilities,  coke  ovens,  blast  furnaces  and 
steel  nnills.  The  ratio  of  sales  to  assets,  therefore,  is  low. 

Although  earnings  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries  during  the 
period  1929-1938,  inclusive,  were  5.9%  of  sales  and  other  revenues,  they 
were  only  \.9%  of  assets. 


Ratio  of  sales  to  U-.tal  assets —  Year  1938 


Millions  cf  Dollars 

Ratio 
of  Sales 

to 
Assets 

Company 

MUlions  of  Dollars 

Ratio 
of  Sales 

to 
Assets 

Company 

Sales 

Total 
Assets 

Sales 

Total 
Assets 

Kroger  Qroc.  &  Baking 

231.3 
793.8 
501.7 
135.2 
154.9 
253.1 

282.4 

42.0 

1,067.0 

102.2 

57.9 
306.5 
286.1 

89.0 
170.1 
276.7 

406.6 

62.5 

1,598.0 

174.4 

399 
259 
175 
175 
91 
91 

67 
67 
59 

General  Electric 

International  Paper 

U.S.  Steel... 

Du  PonfCExcL  O.  M. 

Interest) 

Kennecott  Copper 

Glen  Alden  Coal 

Pennsylvania  R.  R 

Consolidated  Edison... 
Equitable  Office  Build- 
ing 

209.5 
97.5 
611.4 

235.4 
89.1 
35.1 
385.0 
139.4 

3.1 

374.5 

220.7 

1,711.3 

720.0 

342.9 

139.0 

2,  322.  4 

1,061.1 

36.8 

5fl 

Sears,  Roebuck 

General  Foods 

36 

U.S.  Rubber 

American  Tobacco 

International  Harvest- 
er  

American  Woolen 

General  Motors 

Warner  Brothers 

33 
26 
26 
17 
13 

g 

Source:  Moody's  Manual  of  Investments  (except  for  U.  S.  Steel  data). 

Sales  include  aU  revenues  resulting  from  the  sale  of  goods  or  services  or  from  other  activities  in  whicli  the 
company  is  enk-aged.  In  most  instances  the  figures  are  net,  after  deduction  of  the  amount  of  returiis  and 
allowances.  Slight  differences  in  account  classification  exist  but  they  are  not  sufllcient  materially  to  impair 
comparability. 

Total  assets  are  as  of  end  of  fiscal  year,  usually  December  31st. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13769 


RATIO  OF  SALES  TO  TOTAL  ASSETS 

YEAR    1938 


COMPANY 

KROGER  CROC.  &  BAKING 

399» 

SWIFT 

259 

SEARS.  ROEBUCK 

175 

GENERAL  FOODS 

175 

U.  S.  RUBBER 

91 

AMERICAN  TOBACCO 

91 

INTERNATIONAL  HARVESTER 

69 

AMERICAN  WOOLEN 

67 

GENERAL  MOTORS 

67 

WARNER  BROTHERS 

59 

GENERAL  ELECTRIC 

56 

INTERNATIONAL  PAPER 

44 

'U.  S  STEEL 

36 

DU  PONT  (EXCLG.M.  INTEREST) 

33 

KENNECOn  COPPER 

26 

GLEN  ALOEN  COAL 

25 

PENNSYLVANIA  R.  R. 

17 

CONSOLIDATED  EDISON 

13 

EQUITABLE  OFFICE  BIDG 

8 

100% 


200% 


I 


Source.  Mooiy'i  Manuai  o/  Inv^itmenti 


In  the  year  1938  sales  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries  were 
equal  to  36%,  of  total  assets. 

Companies  which  perform  only  a  small  part  of  the  entire  process  of 
production,  fobrication,  and  distribution  characteristically  have  a  high 
ratio  of  soles  to  total  assets.  On  the  other  hand,  highly  integrqted 
companies,  such  as  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation,  which  perform  a  large  port 
of  the  entire  process  from  the  production  of  raw  materials  to  the  fabri- 
cation and  distribution  of  the  finished  product,  as  well  as  companies  such 
as  railroad  and  utility  companies  requiring  a  heavy  investment  "for  the 
services  rendered,  have  a  low  ratio  of  sales  to  total  assets. 

When  turnover  is  high,  profit  margins  con  be  low.  When  turnover  is 
low,  profit  margins  must  be  higher  in  order  to  produce  an  adequate 
return  on  investment. 

Average  monthly  prices  of  common,  and  preferred  stocks —  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
June 
July. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dee. 


Common    Preferred 


$174.94 
180.25 
182.69 
184.06 
174.50 
178.  44 
200.13 
234.  63 
241.  44 
200.25 
170.  38 
172.  81 


$142.  51 
142.50 
142.63 
142.  76 
142.  50 
140.50 
140.13 
141.44 
143. 13 
141. 19 
140.  38 
141.07 


Jan  . 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
June 
July. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Common    Preferred 


$175.31 

$141.88 

183. 06 

141.94 

186. 00 

1 14, 25 

189.  50 

145. 19 

174.75 

145. 13 

162. 69 

145.50 

161.63 

145.  69 

163.88 

145.  94 

164.  25 

148.  69 

151.81 

148.88 

143.88 

146.  38 

140.94 

143. 13 

13770  c^N^'^ 

Average  mon 


iONTRATION  OF  l^CONOMTC  POWER 


thly  prices  of  common  ar^d  preferred  stocks-U.  S.  Sleel  Corporation- 
^  Continued 


Common  I  Prcfprred 


$38.56 
43.69 
45.63 
44.63 
48.25 
46.56 


$94.13 
.75 
109.75 
108.19 
112.88 
113.25 


$48.38 

$118.25 

57.31 

124.50 

64.06 

129.75 

63.69 

127.00 

57.88 

122.63 

61.63 

126.82 

62.50 

126.63 

G7.88 

135.50 

71.25 

138.13 

74.69 

145.00 

75.69 

150.32 

76.75 

143.32 

^Source:  Data  based  on  quotations  on  New  York  Stock  Exchange  fr 


'%^KeIa?e''aveSes  of  monthly  high  ar-^  lo-.v  auotation.s. 


oinniprclal  and  Financial  Chron- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13771 


3yvHS  a3d  savnoQ 

«Oin 

AVERAGE  PRICES  OF  COMMON  AND  PREFERRED  STOCKS 

AVERAGES  OF  MONTHLY  HIGH  AND  ^OW  PRICES  ON  NEW  YORK  STOCK  EXCHANGE 
UNI  1  ED  STATES  STEEL  CORPORATION 

i 

^ 

3 

-Ii 

/^:  - 

X 

-J 

g 

1 3  • 

§s 

« : . 

..  s 

■     ^  — 

- 

§ 

^^-  *- " 

^ 

i 

-»  > 

"^ 

i 

TS        £ 

*JL\«-g 

i 

\  !3^Q 

\"^'  I"' 

Si 

It'  a 

I '  ^ 

§ 

)P  ]i 

a* 

1 

rL 

K, 

1 

*^ 

(   "> 

1 

o\ 

E    ( 

r^a 

-    1                1 

S    > 

'  lu 

^  i           "^ 

V  :^^ 

s            1 

. 

t      c 

}      ^ : 

h" 

1                 t 

S     "~ 

--  .^ 

V 

-     1                  i 

• '' 

:  i          1 

I 

^ 

-  I          1 

:  t    -- 

"p  • 

-  i         ^ 

Y' 

-^      r- 

— — 

-  ~         -! 

-    s              1 

S- 

? 

1 

\ 

|8   8       8SSS5^   o       ooovD^               3 
3avHS  y3d  savnoa                          ^ 

1  J 

g    1 


JEir 

m 


m 


J  1 


124491— 41— pt.  26 15 


13772 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


EARNINGS  AND  CASH  DIVIDENDS  PER  SHARE  OF  COMMON  STOCK 

UNITED  STATES  STEEL  CORPORATION 

50 

I    EARNING 
...       An        _                _                                        JALLLL 

S 

RE 

HAR 

40      ^ 

< 

^     9n                                            1-    JL 

-     Vr                             20     a! 

,.iSAJ.\ ,0  ; 

t ';  4/MP  n 

ffi^l....^L.„  i 

V-4- 10 

-20 

-20 

§i§§i8§sgi 

From  1901  through  1930,  consolidated  earnings  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 
and  subsidiaries  available  for  dividends  on  the  common  stock  of  the  Cor- 
poration averaged  roughly  $  1 0  per  share.  About  one  half  of  this  was  paid 
out  in  dividends  and  most  of  the  remainder  retained  in  the  business  was 
investc  i«,T  plant  and  equiprrient. 

From  1931  through  1938,  earnings  per  share  were  exceeded  by  losses. 
The  common  stock  has  received  no  dividend  since  1 93 1 ,  with  the  excep- 
tion of  $1.00  per  share  paid  in  1937. 

Section  B — Costs 


Relationship  between  total  costs  of  operation  and  volume  of  business — 19S8  condi- 
tions—  United  States  Steel  Corporation  andr  subsidiaries 


Year 

Millions'of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 
Shipped 

Costs-1938 

Conditions 

(Millions  of 

Dollars) 

Year 

Millions  of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 
Shipped 

Costs— 1938 

Conditions 

(Millions  of 

Dollars) 

1927 

13.0 
14.0 
15.1 
11.9 
8.1 
4.4 

954.5 
966.2 
979.0 
838.8 
628.9 
436.0 

1933 

6.2 
6.1 
7.6 
11.0 
13.2 
7.8 

512.0 

1928 

I934 .. 

510.0 

1929 

1935 

610.3 

1930 

818.2 

916.2 

1932 

1938 

614.3 

Average  relationship:  Costs =$182, 100,000  plus  $55.73  per  weighted  ton  of  products  shipped. 

Total  costs  are  adjusted  to  1938  interest,  pension,  wage,  and  tax  rates,  to  1938  price  level,  and  to  1938 
eflBciency. 

Weighted  tonnages  are  actual  tonnages,  adjusted  for  change  in  proportions  of  high  and  low  cost  products 
and  for  the  equivalent  tonnage  of  average  cost  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  represented  by  products 
other  than  steel. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13773 


RELATIONSHIP  BETWEEN  TOTAL  COSTS  OF  OPERATION 
AND  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS  -  1938  CONDITIONS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

1200 

1100 

1000 

to 
900     ^ 

1100 
1000 
^    900 
g     800 
'='     700 
o     600 
^     500 

'' 

■ 

]-' 

■' 

1927 

^': 

1928 

*1929 

1936 

.^ 

i^^ 

^ 

./' 

800     ^ 
700     ° 
600     o 
500     2 

»^ 

^ 

1934 

^.< 

-. 

•'^ 

-1     ^°° 

i     300 

200 

100 

0 

^^ 

^ 

^ 

300     2 

100 
n 

0      1      2     3     4      5     6      7     8     9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16    17    18 
MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

NOTt:   TOTW.  COSTS  «OJU$TtO  TO  1938  INTWEST,  !«.  POBIOH,  AND  WAK  RATES;  TO  1938  «1CE  LEVELS;  AND  TO  1938  EFFICIENCY 

The  average  relatidnshlp  between  volume  and  cost  in  the  operations  of  U^  S.  Steel  Corporation  and 
subsidiaries,  as  Indicated  by  the  costs  for  each  of  the  years  1927  to  1938  adjusted  to  1938  conditions, 
is  such  that  the  total  costs  as  of  1938  for  any  volume  of  business  may  be  estimated  by  multiplying  the 
weighted  tons  of  products  shipped  by  $55.73  and  adding  $182.(00.000.  These  costs  are  exclusive  of  all 
non-operating  income  and  expense  and  of  all  intercompany  transactions,  but  they  cover  all  operations 
of  the  Corporation's  subsidiaries  and,  hence,  do  not  represent  merely  the  cost  of  producing  steel. 

In  using  weighted  tonnages  as  the  measure  of  volume,  the  weighted  tonnage  figure  for  each  year  rep- 
resents the  number  of  gross  tons  of  average  cost  rolled  and  finished  steel  which  would  be  the  cost 
equivalent  of  the  actual  tons  of  various  types  of  steel  and  other  products  sold  during  the  year. 

The  costs  embraced  In  the  $182,100,000  are  those  which  are  incurred  regardless  of  differences  in 
volume  ranging  from  17.7%  to  90.4%  of  annual  ingot  capacity  and,  hence,  may  be  termed  "fixed 
costs".  The  $55.73  per  ton  represents  the  additional  costs  Incurred  with  the  expansion  In  operations 
represented  by  each  weighted  ton  of  product  shipped.  Since  the  average  cost  amounts  to  $55.73  per 
ton  plus  the  pro  rata  portion  of  fxed  costs  and  since  the  $  1 82, 1 00,000  of  fixed  costs  can  be  distributed 
over  more  units  as  production  is  increased,  the  average  cost  per  ton  will  obviously  decrease  as  volume 
rises,  but  the  decrease  is  not  as  great  as  is  sometimes  popularly  supposed. 


J  3774  CONCENTKATKJN  UF  ECONOMIC  TOWER 

Composition  of  total  costs  of  operation  in  relation  to  volume  of  business — United 
States  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Item 

Costs  That 
Must  Be  Met 
Regardless 
of  Operat- 
ing Rate 

Additional 
Costs  for  Each 

Additional 
Weighted  Ton 

of  Product 
Shipped 

$8,300,000 
7,700,000 
29,500,000 
24,200,000 
62,100,000 
2,500,000 
47,800,000 

$0.00 
0  00 

Pensions 

Depreciation  and  Depletion 

2  37 

Taxes  other  than  Social  Security  and  Federal  Income 

I  43 

Payrolls 

29  10 

Social  Security  Taxes 

1  1*1 

Goods  and  Services  Purchased,  etc 

21  67 

$182,100,000 

Data  are  based  on  cost-volume  relationship  indicated  by  1927  to  1938  costs,  adjusted  to  1938  conditions. 

Weighted  tonnages  are  actual  tonnages,  adjusted  for  change  in  proportions  of  high  and  low  cost  products, 
and  for  the  equivalent  tonnage  of  average  cost  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  represented  by  products 
other  than  steel. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13775 


COMPOSITION  OF  TOTAL  COSTS  OF  OPERATION 
IN  RELATION  TO  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 


1200 


3    4.  5    6     7     8    9    10  U  12  13  14  I 

MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL 

TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 


NOTE:    19271938  EXPERIENCE  ADJUSTED  TO  1938  CONDITIONS 


17   IS^lNltfiEsl 


The  total  costs  of  operation  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries  embrace  some  items  of  cost 
which,  at  1938  interest,  wage  and  tax  rates  and  1938  price  levels,  would  remain  constant  throughout  the 
entire  range  of  volume  within  which  the  Corporation  has  operated  during  the  period  1927  to  1938,  while 
other  items  of  cost  vary  directly  with  the  volume  of  business  as  indicated  by  the  volume  of  shipments. 

Of  the  $182,100,000  of  fixed  costs,  over  one-third  represents  payroll  while  less  than  one-sixth  consists 
of  depreciation  and  depletion.  Of  the  items  which  vary  with  Increases  in  volume,  payrolls  and-goods  and 
services  purchased  represent  by  far  the  most  important  items,  representing  over  90%  of  the  additional 
costs  per  ton. 

The  above  costs  cover  all  operations  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries  and  do  not  reflect 
merely  the  cost  of  producing  steel.  The  weighted  tons  shipped,  which  are  the  equivalent  gross  tons  of 
average  cost  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  represented  by  the  actual  tons  of  products  shipped, 
are  used  as  an  indicator  of  the  volume  of  all  operations.  18,000.000  weighted  tons  represent  capacity 
operations. 


13776 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Relationship  between  sales  and  costs — effect  of  reduction  from  average  1938  prices — 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Item 

Fixed 

Variable 
(Per  Weighted 
Ton  Shipped) 

Total  Costa - - 

$182, 100, 000 

$65.73 

$71.86 

Revenues  from  Transportation  and  Miscellaneous  Operations 

5.80 

Total  Sales  and  Revenues,  Average  1938  Prices 

77.66 

$64.67 

5.80 

Tntftl  Salp«  ftnd  'RnvfiTiiifi.q    Avprafffl  1938  PrlfiPS  Less  10% 

70.47 

Cost-volume  relationship  is  that  indicated  by  1927-1938  costs,  adjusted  to  1938  conditions.  Variation  in 
costs  with  changes  in  volume  suppose  no  changes  in  wage,  interest  or  tax  rates,  in  pension  payments,  or  in 
materiaJ  prices.  ,  .  ,        ,  , 

Weighted  tonnages  are  actual  tonnages,  adjusted  for  changes  in  the  proportions  of  high  and  low  cost 
products,  and  for  the  equivalent  tonnage  of  average  cost  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  represented  by 
products  other  than  steel. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13777 


RELATIONSHIP  BETWEEN  SALES  AND  COSTS 

EFFECT  OF  REDUCTION  FROM  AVERAGE  1938  PRICES 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

1100  - 

1000- 

900- 

1    800- 

1       1       1       1       1       1       1 

/ 

A 

4 

1100 
1000 
900 

800     °^ 
700     o 
600     ^ 
500     1 
400     1 
300 
200 
100 
0 

<=>  SAUS  MO  REVENUES 
lacB  SALES  AND  REVENUES 

/ 

^ 

m 

1 

/f 

i 

y 

S 

- 

^ 

L 

EVE 

.^ 

- 

\ 

i 

Q     700  - 
S     600- 
i     500- 

i     ^- 
300- 

200  ^ 

100  - 

oi 

y 

\ 

7 

4 

f 

- 

/ 

i 

f 

r 

— 

TO 

AL 

CO 

TS 

/ 

( 

f 

f 

- 

- 

/ 

f 

i 

V 

- 

- 

4 

/ 

1 

0 
NOTE:   COSTS  ARE 

1     2     3     4     5     6     7     8     9    10   U    12   13  14   15   16   17   1 

MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL 

TONNAGE  Pf?ODUCTS  SHIPPED 

3ASE0  ON  1927-1938  EXPEftlENCC  ADJUSTED  TO  1938  CONDrTIONS 

3 

While  an  increase  in  the  volunr.e  of  steel  sold  results  In  a  considerable  reduction  in  costs  per  ton,  the 
reduction  is  not  so  great  as  to  permit  of  any  sizeable  reduction  in  price  without  a  much  greater  relative 
increase  in  volume.  At  the  average  amount  of  sales  and  revenues  per  weighted  ton  prevailing  in  1938, 
total  sales  and  revenues  would  be  sufficient  to  cover  total  costs  if  shipments  amounted  to  about  8,300,- 
000  weighted  tons  or  more,  which  is  equivalent  to  an  operating  rate  of  40%  to  45%  of  capacity,  de- 
pending upon  the  type  of  products  shipped.  A  reduction  of  10%  from  the  average  1938  prices 
would  so  reduce  the  total  sales  and  revenues  that  the  break-even  point  would  not  be  reached  until  ship- 
ments had  reached  about  12,400,000  weighted  ton:,  as  indicated  by  the  intersection  of  the  dashed  line 
with  the  total  cost  line.  Hence,  a  10%  reduction  in  price  could  be  offset  only  by  a  48.8%  increase  In 
volume.  This  relationship  Is  not  confined  to  the  break-even  point,  for  to  net  any  particular  amount  of 
profit  or  loss  at  prices  10%  below  the  average  1938  level  would  require  a  volume  48.8%  above  that 
required  at  average  1938  prices. 


13778  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  TOWER 

Increases  in  volume  needed  to  compensate  for  various  decreases  in  1038  prices  com- 
pared to  probable  resulting  increases  in  volume-^U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and 
subsidiaries 


Percentage  Reduction 
in  Price 

Percentage 

Increase  in 

Volume 

Needed 

Probable 
Percentage 
Increase, 
Assuming 
Elasticity 
of  1 

Percentage  Reduction 
in  Price 

Percentage 

Increase  in 

Volume 

Needed 

Probable 
Percentage 
Increase, 
Assuming 
Elasticity 
ofl 

1 

3.4 
7.0 
10.9 
15.1 
19.6. 
24.5 
29.8 
35.5 
41.8 
48.8 
56.4 

1.0 
2.0 
3.1 
4.2 
5.3 
6.4 
7.5 
8.7 
9.9 
n.  1 

12.4 

12 

64.8 
74.2 
84.8 
96.7 
110.3 
125.8 
143.9 
165.0 
190.3 
220.8 

13.6 

2 - 

13 

14.9 

3.. 

16.3 

4 

15 

17  7 

5 

16 

19  1 

6 

17 

20  5 

7 

18 

22  0 

8       

19 

23  5 

9     

20 

25  0 

10      

21 

26  6 

Estimates  of  increase  in  volume  needed  based  on  cost-volume  relationship  indicated  by  1927-1938  costs 
a<ljusted  to  1938  conditions,  and  suppose  no  change  in  wage,  interest,  or  tax  rates,  in  pension  payments,  or 
in  material  prices. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13779 


INCREASES  IN  VOLUME  NEEDED  TO  COMPENSATE  FOR 

VARIOUS  DECREASES  IN  1938  PRICES 

COMPARED  TO  PROBABLE  RESULTING  INCREASES  IN  VOLUME 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

240 


220 


200 


UJ 

180 

S 

—> 

^ 

160 

z 

(O 

140 

s 

120 

z 

Ui 

100 

s 

^ 

80 

'^ 

60 

40 

20 

n 

r 

(1 

r 

r 

r 

] 

, 

- 

NCR 
N  VO 
NF 

^SES 
LUM 
OED 



n 

' 

,  , 

,i: 

^.4* 

1 

, 

■■ 

PROBABLE 
RESULTING 
'INCREASES 
IN  VOLUME 


0  1  2  3  4  5  6  7  8  9  10  11  12  13  14  15  16  17  18  19  20  21 
PERCENTAGE  DECREASES  FROM  AVERAGE  1938  PRICES 


NOTE:   PROBABLE  RESULTING  INCREASES  IN  VOLUME  BASEDON  ASSUMPTION  THAT  ELASTICITY  OF  DEMAND  EQUALS  1. 


The  Increases  in  the  volume  of  s+eel  soH  which  would  have  been  likely  to  have  resulted 
fronn  decreases  in  the  average  1938  prices  would  have  been  but  a  small  fraction  of  the 
percentage  Increases  necessary  to  compensate  for  the  respective  reductions. 

The  elasticity  of  demand  for  a  product  is  measured  by  the  ratio  of  the  relative  resulting 
increase  in  the  volume  to  the  relative  decrease  in  price.  Both  actual  business  experience 
and  statistical  analyses  Indicate  that  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  is  less  than  I .  Thus 
cutting  prices  in  half  could  no  more  than  double  volume.  It  is  on  the  basis  of  an  elasticity 
of  I  that  the  probable  Increase  in  volume  has  been  computed. 

The  estimate  of  the  Increase  In  volume  needed  takes  into  consideration  the  effect  of  the 
increased  volume  In  reducing  costs  per  ton. 


13780  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Estimated  additions  to  19S8  deficit — How  deficit  would  have  increased  if  -prices  had 
been  reduced  and  volume  had  increased  to  same  relative  extent — U.  S.  Steel  Cor- 
poration and  subsidiaries 


Percentage  Reduction  in  Price 

Estimated  Ad- 
ditional Loss, 

Assuming 
Elasticity  of 
Demand  for 

Steel  of  1 

Percentage  Reduction  in  Price 

Estimated  Ad- 
ditional Loss, 
Assuming 
Elasticity  of 
Demand  for 
Steel  of  1 

1 

$3,900,000 
7,900,000 
12, 000, 000 
16,200,000 
20, 500, 000 
24,900,000 
29,300,000 
33,900,000 
38,500,000 
43,300,000 

jj 

$48  100,000 

2 

12 .-. 

13 

14                   

53, 100,  000 

3 

58,  200,  000 

68,  700,  000 

74,  200,  000 

17 ---. 

79,  800,  000 

18 

85,  500,  000 

19 _ 

91,400,000 

20 -  — -- 

97, 400,  000 

Estimated  additional  loss  based  on  cost-volume  relationship  indicated  by  1527-1938  costs  adjusted  to  1938 
conditions,  and  supposes  no  change  in  wage,  interest,  or  tax  rates,  in  pension  payments,  or  in  material  prices . 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13781 


ESTIMATED  ADDITIONS  TO  1938  DEFICIT 

HOW  DEFICIT  WOULD  HAVE  INCREASED  IF  PRICES  HAD  BEEN  REDUCED 
AND  VOLUME  HAD  INCREASED  TO  SAME  RELATIVE  EXTENT 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
96 872 


ESTIMATED  ADDITIONS  TO 

DEFICIT  IF  PRICES  HAD  BEEN 

REDUCED  AS  'NDCATED 


792 


712 
63.2 
55.2 

H-47.2 
392 
3L2 

H-  232 
15.2 


PERCENTAGE  REBUCTION  IN  1938  AVERAGE  PRICE 


The  elasticity  of  demand  for  a  product  is  measured  by  the  i 
increase  in  volume  to  the  relative  decrease  in  price. 


itio  of  the  resulting  relative 


Analyses  of  the  demand  for  steel  indicate  that  steel  has  an  elasticity  of  demand  no 
greater  than  I.  Thus,  cutting  steel  prices  in  half  could  no  more  than  double  the  volume. 

If  an  attempt  had  been  made  to  stimulate  the  volume  of  steel  sold  during  the  recession 
of  1938  by  decreasing  prices  further  than  was  actually  required  by  competition,  the  in- 
crease in  volume  which  would  have  resulted  would  not  have  been  sufficient  to  compen- 
sate for  the  price  reduction.  On  the  contrary,  any  further  decrease  in  prices  would  have 
served  but  to  increase  the  1938  deficit,  and  the  greater  the  reduction,  the  more  the 
deficit  would  have  increased. 


13782  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Relationship  between  sales  and  costs — Effect  of  reduction  from  2nd  half  of  1938 
prices — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Item 

FUcd 

Variable  (Per 

Weighted 
Ton  Shipped) 

Total  Costs 

$182, 100, 000 

$55.73 

, 

5.80 

73.13 

Sales  Average  2nd  Half  1938  Prices  Less  10% 

$60  60 

Revenues  from  Transportation  and  Miscellaneous  Operations 

5  80 

Total  Sales  and  Revenues,  A-verage  2nd  Half  1938  Prices  Less  10% 

66  40 

Cost-volume  relationship  is  that  indicated  by  1927-1938  costs,  adjusted  to  1938  conditions.  Variation 
in  costs  with  changes  in  volume  suppose  no  changes  in  wage,  interest  or  tax  rates,  in  pension  payments,  or 
in  material  prices. 

Sales  per  weighted  ton  prevailing  in  2nd  half  of  1938  represent  the  average  sales  per  weighted  ton  for  1938 
reduced  proportionately  to  the  extent  to  which  the  selling  value  per  weighted  ton  or  rolled  and  finished 
steel  products  shipped  during  the  2nd  half  of  1938  was  less  than  the  average  selling  value  of  rolled  and 
finished  steel  products  for  the  entire  year. 

Weighted  tonnages  are  actual  tonnag&s,  adjusted  for  changes  in  the  proportions  of  high  and  low  cost  prod- 
ucts, and  for  the  equivalent  tonnage  of  average  cost  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  represented  by 
products  other  than  steel. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13783 


RELATIONSHIP  BETWEEN  SALES  AND  COSTS 

EFFECT  OF  REDUCTION  FROM  2nd  HALF  1938  PRICES 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

1100  - 

1 

1100 
1000 
900 

800     1 
700     o 
600     o 
500     1 
400     - 
300 
200 
100 
0 

c i  SALES  AND  REVENUE 

y 

- 

/ 

Y 

/ 

/ 

\ 

// 

fe 

^ 

\ 

i 

f 

(f 

/f 

\ 

/ 

a     7°°  ~ 

4 

/ 

(O 

/: 

V 

n 

r 

o     5°°  " 

/ 

'I 

Y 

TO 

AL 

CO 

TS 

s     ^°°" 

/ 

/ 

//* 

r 

200^ 

/ 

J 

t 

^ 

' 

~ 

- 

~ 

0^ 

y 

0     1     2     3     4     5    6     7     8     9    10   11    12   13  14   15  16   17   1 

MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL 

TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

NOTE     COSTS  ARE  BASED  ON  1927.1338  EXPERIENCE.  ADJUSTED  TO  1938  CONDITIONS 

3 

The  reduction  in  the  cost  per  ton  of  steel  resulting  from  an  increased  volume  of  production  Is  not  so 
great  as  to  permit  of  any  sizeable  reduction  in  price  without  a  much  greater  relative  Increase  In  volume. 
At  the  average  amount  of  sales  and  revenues  per  weighted  ton  prevailing  during  the  second  half  of 
1938,  after  the  June  24,  1938  price  reduction,  total  sales  and  revenues  would  be  sufficient  to  cover 
total  costs  if  annual  shipments  amounted  to  about  IO'/2  million  weighted  tons  or  more,  which  is  equiva- 
lent to  an  operating  rate  of  about  50%  to  55%  of  capacity,  depending  upon  the  type  of  product 
shipped.  A  reduction  of  10%  from  this  price  level  would  so  reduce  the  total  sales  and  revenues  that  the 
break-even  point  would  not  be  reached  until  over  17  million  weighted  tons  were  shipped,  as  Indicated 
by  the  Intersection  of  the  dashed  line  with  the  total  cost  line.  This  would  mean  that  the  Corporation  and 
its  subsidiaries  would  not  break  even  until  operations  had  reached  907o  of  capacity.  In  which  case  opera- 
tions would  have  to  be  carried  on  at  the  impossible  rate  of  1 30%  of  capacity  to  earn  a  return  as 
modest  as  SYo  o"  t^ie  investment  in  tangible  assets. 


13784 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  P0W1<:R 


Increases  in  volume  needed  to  compensate  for  various  decreases  in  2nd  half  1938  -prices 
compared  to  probable  resulting  increases  in  volume — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and 
subsidiaries 


Percentage  Reduction 
in  Price 

Percentage 

Increase  in 

Volume 

Needed 

Probable 
Percentage 
Increase, 
Assuming 
Elasticity 
ofl 

Percentage  Reduction 
in  Price 

Percentage 

Increase  in 

Volume 

Needed 

Probable 
Percentage 
Increase, 
Assuming 
Elasticity 
ofl 

^ 

4.0 
8.4 
13.1 
18  3 
24.0 
30.2 
37.2 
44.8 
53.5 
63.1 
74.1 

1.0 
2.0 
3.1 
4.2 
5.3 
6.4 
7.5 
8.7 
9.9 
11.1 
12.4 

12 

86.7 
K)1.3 
118.3 
138.4 
162.7 
192.4 
229.7 
277.9 
342.6 
434.1 

13  6 

2 

13 

14  9 

3 

14 

16  3 

4 

15 

17  7 

5 

16 

19  1 

6 

17 

20  5 

7 

18 

22  0 

8                                  -  -- 

19 

23  5 

10          

21 

26  6 

Estimates  of  increase  in  volume  needed  based  on  cost-volume  relationship  indicated  by  1927-1938  costs 
adjusted  to  1938  conditions,  and  suppose  no  change  in  wage,  interest,  or  tax  rates,  in  pension  payments,  or 
in  material  prices. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13785 


INCREASES  IN  VOLUME  NEEDED  TO  COMPENSATE  FOR 

VARIOUS  DECREASES  IN  2nd  HALF  1938  PRICES 

COMPARED  TO  PROBABLE  RESULTING  INCREASES  IN  VOLUME 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

440 


7    8    9   10  U  12  13  14  15  16  17  18  19  20  21 
PERCENTAGE  DECREASES  IN  PRICES 


NOTE:    PROBABLE  RESULTING 


IN  VOLUME  BASED  ON  ASSUMPTION  1 


r  ELASTICITY  Of  DEMAND  EQUALS  I 


The  probable  increase  In  the  volume  of  sales  which  would  result  from  a  decrease  in  steel  prices  from 
the  level  prevailing  subsequent  to  the  June  24,  1938  price  reduction,  is  but  a  small  fraction  of  the  per- 
centage increase  which  would  be  necessary  to  compensate  for  the  price  decrease.  The  divergence  be- 
tween the  increase  in  volume  needed  and  the  increase  in  volume  which  would  probably  result  from  the 
price  reduction  is  even  greater  than  the  divergence  with  respect  to  reductions  from  tne  average  1938 
prices. 

The  elasticity  of  demand  for  a  product  is  measured  by  the  ratio  of  the  relative  resulting  increase  in  the 
volume  to  the  relative  decrease  In  price.  Both  actual  business  experience  and  statistical  analyses  indicate 
that  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  Is  less  than  I.  Thus  cutting  prices  in  half  coukJ  no  more  than  double 
volume.  It  is  on  the  basis  of  an  elasticity  of  I  that  the  probable  Increase  In  volume  has  been  computed. 
The  estimate  of  the  increase  in  volume  needed  takes  into  consideration  the  effect  of  the  increased  vol- 
ume in  reducing  costs  per' ton. 


13786  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Earnings  per  hour  and  steel  prices 

[Earnings  per  hour=earninBs  per  hour  of  all  employees  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries; 
steel  prices=Iron  Age  composite  price  of  finished  steel] 


1929 

1830 

1931....:.. 
1932 

1933 

Jan 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug 

Sep 

Oct _ 

Nov 

Dec 

1934 

Jan 

Feb.. 

Mar 

Apr 

May 

Jun 

Jul _. 

Aug....... 

Sep 

uct 

Nov 

Dec 

1935 

Jan 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May 

Jun 

Jul.. 

Aug 

Sep 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

1936 

Jan 

Feb 


Hourly  earnings 


Cents 
per 
hour 


68.7 
69.1 
61.4 


56.9 
57.7 
57.3 
56.1 
54.3 
53.3 
56.3 
59.6 
62.- 7 


66.0 
66.5 
65.5 
72.0 
71.0 
70.6 
71.7 
72.3 
73.0 
72.3 
73.0 
73.1 


72.5 
73.4 
72.7 
73.0 
72.7 
73.3 
72.5 
72.5 
73.0 
73.3 
74.2 
73.9 


1926= 
100 


102.8 
103.0 
103.6 
92.1 


85.3 
86.5 
85.9 
84.1 
81.4 
79.9 
84.4 
89.4 
94.0 
96.9 


99.0 
99.7 
98.2 
107.9 
106.4 
105.8 
107.5 
108.4 
109.4 


108.7 
110.0 
109.0 
109.4 
109.0 
109.9 
108.7 
108.7 
109,4 
109.9 
111.2 
110.8 


Steel  prices 


Cents 

per 
pound 


2.209 
2.048 
1.957 
1.901 


1.885 
1.873 
1.867 
1.817 
1.802 


1.890 
1.9,50 
1.933 
1.945 


1.945 
1.945 
1.945 
1.988 
2.  llf 
2.11 
2.056 
2  056 
2  056 
2.056 
2.  056 
2  056 


2.056 
2.056 
2  056 
2  056 
2.056 
2.05 
2.05 
2.05 
2.05 
2.062 
2.062 
2.062 


95.4 
88.5 
84.5 
82.1 


81.4 
80.9 
80.6 
78.5 
77.8 
78.6 
81.1 
81.3 
81.6 
84.2 
83.5 
84.0 


88.8 
88.8 


1936 

Mar 

Apr  

May 

Jun 

Jul :.. 

Aug 

Sep 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

1937 

Jan 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug  - 

Sep 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

1938 
Jan 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug 

Sep. - 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

1939 

Jan 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug 


Hourly  earnings       Steel  prices 


Cents 
per 
hour 


72.8 
73.0 
72.4 
73.7 
74.2 
73.9 
72.5 
71.9 
75.0 
77.8 


78.0 
78.5 
83.1 
89.8 
S9.5 
89.4 
90.1 
89.4 
87.7 


89.6 
89.2 
90.8 
91.0 
91.9 
93.1 
90.6 
90.1 
89.0 
89.2 
88.9 


89.5 
90.2 
89.0 
89.9 
91.2 
89.6 


109.1 
109.4 

108.5 
110.5 
111.2 
110.8 
108.7 
107.8 
112.4 
116.6 


116.9 
117.7 
124.6 
134.6 
134.2 
134.0 
135.1 
134.0 
131.  5 
129.4 
129.8 
131.5 


133.0 
134.3 
133.7 
136.1 
136.4 
137.8 
139.6 
135.  8 
135.1 
133.4 
133.7 
133.3 


134.0 
134.8 
134.2 
135.  2 
133.4 
134.8 
136.7 
134.3 


Cents 

per 
pound 


2.021 
2.028 
2.028 
2.033 
2.091 
2.091 
2.096 
2.116 
2.116 
2.199 


2.249 
2.249 
2.459 
2.512 
2.512 
2.512 
2.512 
2.512 
2.512 
2.512 
2.512 
2.512 


2.512 
2.512 
2.512 
2.512 
2.606 
2.459 
2.300 
2.300 
2.293 
2.  255 
2.286 
2.286 


2.286 
2.286 
2.286 
2.286 
2.2.16 
2.236 
2.236 
2.236 


87.3 
87.6 
87.6 
87.8 
90.3 
90.3 
90  5 
91.4 
91.4 
95.0 


97.1 
97.1 
106.2 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 


108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.3 
106.2 
99.4 
99.4 
99.0 
97.4 
98.7 
98.7 


98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
97.5 
96.6 
96.6 
96.6 


Steel  prices  are  monthly  averages  of  weekly  figures. 

The  1926  base  for  earnings  per  hour  of  all  employees  of  U.  8.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries  was  esti- 
mated from  data  on  the  total  steel  industry  compiled  by  National  Industrial  Conference  Board,  as  Cor- 
poration data  are  not  available  prior  to  1929. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13787 


EARNINGS  PER  HOUR  AND  STEEL  PRICES 

1926  =  100 


r\ 

A 

w^ 

EARNINGS 

f 

(US, 
SUBS 

S.C.  »N0 

; 

r 

P 

n 

% 

\, 

/ 

J 

f 

=^ 

■^ 

s 

W- 

J  STEEL  PRICE 
-^       (IRON  *GEI 

\j 

^ 

• 

1930   1931   1932   1933   1934   1935   1936   1937   1938   1939   1940 


So^'cc    Srte/  Pf-ces  -  '^oo  Age  ctyrpos'ti^  p'<ce  o 


Payroll  is  such  an  Important  element  of  costs  in  steel  production  that 
increases  in  earnings  per  hour  usually  cause  higher  steel  prices.  However, 
earnings  per  hour  are  now  about  35%  above  the  level  of  1926,  wherisas 
steel  prices  are  slightly  lower  than  they  were  in  that  year.  Since  wages 
an<J  salaries  average  about  45%  of  the  costs  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 
and  subsidiaries,  a  35%  Increase  In  hourly  earnings  causes  approximately 
a  l57o  increase  in  total  costs. 


124491— 41— 'pt  26 14 


13788  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Unadjusted  costs  and  volume  of  business  compared  with  estimated  costs  for  correspond- 
ing volumes  under  1938  conditions — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Year 

Millions  of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 
Shipped 

Unadjusted 

Costs 

(Millions 

of  Dollars) 

Year 

MiUions  of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 
Shipped 

Unadjusted 

Costs 
(Millions 
of  Dollars) 

1926 

14.9 
13.0 
14.0 
15.1 
11.9 
8.1 
4.4 

956.7 
867.0 
884.5 

724^9 
539.4 
361.2 

1933 

6.2 
6.1 
7.6 
11.0 
13.2 
7.8 

414  4 

1927 

1934 

442.9 

1928 

1935 

539  2 

1929 

1936 

731  8 

1930 

1937 

900  5 

1931 

1938 

614  5 

1932 

Estimated  relationship  of  cost  to  Volume  under  1938  conditions:  Costs =$182, 100,000  plus  $55.73  per 
weighted  ton  of  products  shipped. 

Unadjusted  costs  are  as  per  profit  and  loss  statements  submitted  to  Federal  Trade  Commission,  February 
7.  1939,  exclusive  of  Federal  income  taxes,  miscellaneous  non-operating  income  and  expense,  and  of  inter- 
company items. 

Estimated  relationship  of  cost  to  volume  is  that  indicated  by  1927-1938  costs  adjusted  to  1938  interest, 
tax,  pension  and  wage  rates;  to  1938  price  levels;  and  to  1938  eflBciency. 

Weighted  tonnages  are  actual  tonnages,  adjusted  for  change  in  proportions  of  high  and  low  cost  products 
and  for  the  equivalent  tonnage  of  average  cost  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  represented  by  products 
other  than  steel. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13789 


UNADJUSTED  COSTS  AND  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS  COMPARED  WITH 
EST.  COSTS  FOR  CORRESP.  VOLUMES  UNDER  1938  CONDITIONS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

1100 
1000 

1  900 

=i     800 

o 

°     700 

o     600 

-     500 

2  400 

i   3°o 

200 

100 

0 

/- 

1100 
1000 

CO 

900     ^ 
800     g 
700     ° 
600     S 
500     - 
400     2 
300     1 
200 
100 
0 

,'-' 

' 

'Y'-' 

'' 

,^- 

1928 

'"■ 

.^  'r936 

1930 

1933^ 

-i 

.,'' 

IW 

j931 

^.' 

''■ 

[.934 

_^- 

■-'' 

1932 

1933 

'-' 

UNADJUSTED  COSTS 

EST.  COSTS  UNDER  '38  CONDITIONS 

' 

L 

^r 

" 

0      1      2      3     4      5     6      7      8      9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16    17    18 
MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

Total  costs  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries,  exclusive 
of  Federal  income  toxes,  the  net  amount  of  miscellaneous  non-operating 
income  end  expense,  ond  of  inter-company  items,  hove  been  greater  for 
a  given  volume  of  sfiipmenfs  in  recent  years  tfion  formerly.  Tfie  year  1938, 
for  instance,  may  be  compared  with  1935  and  1931,  while  1937  may  te 
contrasted  with  1927  and  1928. 

The  dotted  line  represents  the  estimated  total  costs  ot  the  various  volumes 
if  1938  interest,  tox,  ond  wage  rates,  pension  payments,  material  prices 
and  technological  conditions  had  prevoiled  throughout  the  period.  The 
combined  effect  of  the  various  factors  increasing  and  decreasing  costs, 
such  OS  increased  woges,  taxes,  and  material  prices,  and  improved  tech- 
nology and  efficiency  has  been  to  raise  the  cost  level  obove  the  levels  of 
eoch  of  the  preceding  yeors. 


How  costs  have  increased- 


U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiari 
with  1931 


-1938  compared 


Item 

1931 

1938 

Per  Cent 

Increase 

(•38  over 

'31 

Payroll  (Wages  and  Salaries) 

$253, 178, 649 
197, 874, 481 
47, 317, 895 
34, 247, 632 
$551, 126,  423 
18,  507,  766 
7, 676,  744 

$275, 364, 898 

237,454,811 

49,  193.  448 

48,842,131 

$611,  400, 162 

544,874 

6, 659, 253 

9 

Goods  and  Services  Purchased  from  Others 

20 

Depreciation  and  Depletion 

4 

Taxes  (Federal,  State  and  Local) 

43 

Sales  and  Other  Revenues 

Earnings  (Befnre  Interest) 

-97 

Rolled  and  Finished  Steel  Products  ShTp]^d  (Tons) 

-13 

Payroll  represents  wages  and  b  'aries  paid  to  all  employees  of  all  companies.  The  relatively  small  con- 
struction payroll  has  been  excluded,  as  constituting  capital  expenditures  subsequently  recoverable  through 
depr-^ciation  charges. 

Sales  and  other  revenues  represent  tie  total  amount  available  for  the  payment  of  all  expenses  and  ether 
obligations.  In  eliminating  inter-compary  business,  amounts  applicable  to  transportation  companies  were 
partially  estimated. 


13790 


CONfENTTlATION  OF  ErONOAriC  T»OWRR 


HOW  COSTS  HAVE  INCREASED 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
1938  COMPARED  WITH  1931 


.— — ""depranddepl  ^- 


(WAGES  AND  SALARIES) 


In  1938,  shipments  of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  were  about 
1,000,000  tons  less  then  in  1931.  However,  largely  because  of  higher  prices  and  differences  in  the  types 
of  products  sold,   sales  and   other   revenues  were  opproximotely  $60,000,000  higher  than  in   1931. 


But  in  1938 
Payroll  was  up 

Goods  and  Services  Purchased  were  up 
Depreciation  end  Depletion  were  up 
Taxes  were  up 

making  a  total  increase  in  cesfs  of 

with  the  result  that 
Earnings  before  Interest  were  down 


$22,000,000 
40,000.000 
2,000,000 
14,000,000 

$78,000,000 


CONCKNTl{A'ri(»N  Of'  l':c:(»N()MlC  TOWEIl  1371)1 

How  costs  have  increased —  If.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries— 1037  compared 
with  1929-'S0  average 


Item 

I929-'30  Average 

1937 

Per  Cent 
Increase 
'37  over 
'29--30 

Payroll  (Wages  and  Salaries) 

$387, 416, 114 
306,010,460 
60, 912, 142 
51,511,936 
$967, 149,  950 
161,299,298 
13,429,325 

$426,  330, 944 
353,  434,  790 
60,861,212 
88, 048, 237 
$1,028,760,629 
100,085,446 
12,  789,  841 

10 

Goods  aud  Services  Purchased  from  Others 

16 

Depreciation  and  Depletion 

Rolled  and  Finished  Steel  Products  Shipped  (Tons) 

-5 

Payroll  represents  wages  and  salaries  paid  to  all  employees  of  all  companies.  The  relatively  small  con- 
struction payroll  has  been  excluded  as  constituting  capital  e.xpenditures  subsequently  recoverab'e  through 
depreciation  charges. 

Sales  and  other  revenues  represent  the  total  amount  available  for  the  payment  of  all  expenses  and  other 
obligations.  In  eliminating  inter-company  business,  amounts  applicable  to  transportation  companies  were 
partially  estimated. 


13792 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


HOW  COSTS  HAVE  INCREASED 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
1937  COMPARED  WITH  1929-'30  AVERAGE 


,^-'         TAXES     ^^ 


.^— -D'EPR.  AND  DEPj ■^-^ 


In  1937,  shipments  of  ro'led  and  finished  steel  products  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  were  about 
640,000  tons  less  tbon  the  overoge  of  1929-'30.  However,  lorgely  because  of  hgher  prices  and  differ- 
tnces  in  the  tyoes  of  products  sold,  soles  and  other  revenues  were  opproximotoly  $62,000,000  higher 
'fhj„  ,n  1929 -JO. 

But  in  1937 
Payroll  was  up  $39,000,0iD0 

Goods  and  Services  Purchased  were  up  47,000,000 

Taxes  were  l  p  37,000,000 

.naming  a  total  increase  m  costs  of         $123,000,000 
with  the  result  that 
Earnings  before  Interest  were  down  $61,000,000 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13793 

Composite  mill  net  yield  and  cost  per  weighted  ton  shipped — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 

and  subsidiaries 

[1926  =  100] 


Composite  Mill  Net  Yield 


Jan       Feb      Mar      Apr      May      Jun        Jul       Aug 


Oct       Nov      Dec 


1926- 
1927.. 
1928.. 
1929.. 
1930.. 
1931.. 
1932.. 
1933.. 
1934-. 
1935.. 
1936.. 
1937.. 
1938.. 


94.2 
92.4 

7816 
77.0 
87.1 
92.1 
89.0 
91.4 
105.4 
93.2 


94.2 
91.6 

79!  1 
76.0 
88.1 
92.0 


97.0 

93^9 
91.2 
82.3 

75!  6 
87.4 
91.9 
87.6 
93.3 
105.9 
95.8 


78.7 
75.0 
87.1 


95.8 
104.3 
95.1 


100.1 
95.9 
94.3 
94.2 

8l!4 
77.7 
74.5 
88.5 
92.0 
87.1 
98.0 
104.4 
94.8 


96.4 
93.8 
94.3 

80^4 
79.2 
74.6 
87.4 
91.2 


96.3 
92.9 
95.0 
86.6 
79.9 
79.5 
73.5 
91.8 
90.5 
87.3 
101.6 
97.9 
91.4 


96.3 
92.4 
95.4 
86.0 
79.8 
79.3 
75.0 
92.9 


101.9 
96.2 
91.4 


99.9 
95.9 
92.7 
94.5 
85.0 
81.9 
79.0 
77.2 
91.9 
90.0 
88.8 
103.4 
95.9 
91.4 


99.6 
94.9 
92.9 
94.3 


79.4 
9<.3 
89.6 

105!  7 
93.7 
92.2 


99.9 
95.2 
93.9 
94.3 


78.2 
82.6 
92.5 

90!  0 

104.8 
91.6 
93.0 


99.8 
93.5 
93.7 
94.0 
82.0 
80.2 
77.9 
83.5 
89.9 
89.6 
90.6 
105.3 
92.2 


The  composite  mill  net  yield  index  represents  the  amount,  relative  to  that  for  1926,  received  per  ton  by 
U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  (after  freight)  from  sales  of  a  representative  constant  assortment  of  all 
principal  products. 


Cost  per  Weighted 
Ton  Shipped 

Year 

Cost  per  Weighted 
Ton  Shipped 

Year 

Actual 
Cost 

Estimated 
Cost  at 
1926  Vol- 
ume 

Actual 
Cost 

Estimatea 
Cost  at 
1926  Vol- 
ume 

1926 

100.0 
103.6 
98.3 
91.8 

105!  6 
129.6 

100.0 
101.1 
97.2 
92.0 
92.8 
92.2 
91.7 

1933.  .     . 

105.8 
115.0 
112.7 
105.9 
108.7 
124.5 

1927 - - 

1934. 

1928 

1935 

96  6 

1929 

1936 

1930 

1937 

106  3 

1931 

1938 

107  6 

1932... 

Actual  cost  per  weighted  ton  shipped  is  total  cost,  exclusive  of  bond  interest.  Federal  income  taxes,  mis- 
cellaneous non-operating  income  and  expense,  and  of  inter-company  items,  for  all  subsidiaries  of  U.  S. 
Steel  Corporation,  divided  by  the  number  of  weighted  tons  shipped.  Weighted  tonnages  are  actual  ton- 
nages, adjusted  for  change  in  proportions  of  high  and  low  cost  products  and  for  the  equivalent  tonnage  of 
average  cost  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  represented  by  products  other  than  steel.  The  cost  of  opera- 
tions not  related  to  the  production  of  steel  is  included  in  total  cost,  but  since  such  cost  is  a  small  percentage 
of  the  total  and  since  the  other  operations  tend  to  expand  and  contract  with  the  volume  of  steel  production, 
the  relative  change  in  the  total  cost  per  weighted  ton  may  be  considered  fairly  indicative  of  the  change  in 
the  cost  of  producing  steel. 

Estimated  cost  if  1926  volume  maintained  is  the  actual  cost  per  weighted  ton  shipped  adjusted  to  1926 
volume  on  the  assumption  that  the  percentage  change  in  the  average  cost  per  ton  as  the  result  of  a  given 
change  in  volume  would  have  been  the  same  in  each  of  the  respective  years  as  it  is  estimated  to  have  been 
under  1938  conditions. 


13794  C'TONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Section  C — Prices 
Average  yearly  base  prices  of  principal  sleel  products — reported  by  Iron  Age 


Rails 

Structural 
Shapes 

Plates 

Standard  Pipe 

Bars 

Year 

Dollars 
per 
Gross 
Ton 

1924 
=  100 

Cents 

per 
Pound 

1924 
=  100 

Cents 

per 
Pound 

1924 
=  100 

Dollars 

^% 
Ton 

1924 
=  100 

Cents 

per 
Pound 

1924 
=  100 

1924 

1025       -....- 

43.00 
43.00 
43.00 
43.00 
43.00- 
43.00 
43.00 
43.00 
42. 44^ 
39.26 
36.37 
36.37 
36.59 
41.86 
41.77 
40.00 

100.0 
100.0 
100.0- 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
98.7 
91.3 
84.6 
84.6 
85.1 
97.3 
97.1 
93.0 

2.19 

i;9.5 
1.83 
1.87 
1192 
1.69 
1.62 
1.57 
1.68 
1.78 
1.80 
1.85 
2.21 
2.17 
2.10 

100.0 
90.9 

83!  6 
85.4 
87.7 
77.2 
74.0 
71.7 
76.7 
81.3 
82.2 
84.5 
100.9 
99.1 
95.9 

2.12 
1.91 
1.88 
1.82 
1.87 
1.93 
1.69 
1.62 
1.57 
1.61 
1.78 
1.80 
1.85 
2.21 
2.17 
2.10 

100.0 
90.1 

85!  8 
88.2 
91.0 
79.7 
76.4 
74.1 
75.9 
84.0 
84.9 
87.3 
104.2 
102.4 
99.1 

70.30 
70.30 
70.30 
69.57 
69.84 
70.30 
67.45 
6,5.29 
64.89 
61.63 
66.32 
68.40 
62.01 
69.17 
67.00 
63.00 

100.0 
100.0 
100.0 
99.0 
99.3 
100.0 
95.9 
92.9 
92.3 
87.7 
94.3 
97.3 

98!  4 
95.3 
89.6 

2.20 
2.02 
2.00 
1.84 
1.87 
1.92 
1.71 
1.63 
1.57 
1.64 
1.81 
1.81 
1.93 
2.40 
2.35 
2.21 

100.0 

1926 

1927 

1928 

85  0 

1929 

87  3 

1930 

77  7 

1931 

74  1 

1932 

71  4 

1933 

74.5 

1934 

82.3 

1935             

1936    

87.7 

1937 

109.1 

1938 

106.8 

1939  > 

100  5 

AVire  Nails 

Hot  Rolled  Sheets 

Cold  Rolled  Sheets 

Tin  Plato 

Year 

Dollars 
per  Keg 

1924  =  100 

Cents 

per 
Pound 

1924  =  100 

Cents 

per 
Pound 

1924=100 

DoUars 

per  Base 

Box 

1924=100 

1924      

2.89 
2.72 
2.65 
2.54 

2^57 
2.10 
1.88 
1.95 
1.99 
2.52 
2.53 
2.13 
2.67 
2.60 

100.0 
94.1 
91.7 
87.9 
89.3 

T2.7 
65.1 
67.5 

87.2 
87.5 
73.7 
92.4 
90.0 
84.4 

.     2.79 
2.45 
2.37 
2.20 
2.04 
2.12 
1.99 
1.86 
1.71 
1.62 
1.85 
1.85 
1.92 
2.35 
2.25 
2.08 

100.0 
87.8 
84.9 
78.9 
73.1 
76.0 
71.3 
66.7 
61.3 
58.1 
66.3 
66.3 
68.8 
84.2 
80.6 
74.6 

5.00 
4.39 
4.30 
4.17 
4.03 
4.06 
3.64 
3.13 
2.80 
2.48 
2.96 
2.95 
3.02 
3.49 
3.31 
3.13 

100.0 
87.8 
86.0 
83.4 
80.6 
81.2 
72.8 
62.6 
56.0 

5.50 
5.50 
5.50 
5.48 
5.25 
5.35 
5.19 
4.94 
4.69 
4.43 
5.25 
5.25 
5.25 
5.22 
5.31 
5.00 

100.0 

1925  

100.0 

1926 

100.0 

1927 

99  6 

1928 

95.5 

1929 

97.3 

1930 

94.4 

1931 

.89.8 

1932               

85.3 

1933 

49.6 

80.5 

1934 

59.2 

95.5 

1935 

59.0 
60.4 
69.8 
66.2 
62.6 

95.  5 

1936 

95.5 

1937 

94.9 

1938 

96.5 

90.9 

Data  for  1939  are  on  basis  of  first  8  months. 


CONCENTKATIUN  OF  ECUNlLMJC  I'UWEU 


18795 


AVERAGE  YEARLY  BASE  PRICES  OF  PRINCIPAL  STEEL  PRODUCTS 

REPORTED  BY  IRON  AGE  1924  =  100 


II 

r'"j:  T"Ti- 

TTT':  ""' JV 

i  /il»    \.  .u« 

rw«   ^      S 

RA 

t-    I     'i'm- 

;-l  I    -..-  --|;;f- 

'{' "    "    Y 

/ 80      ---   ^s,^j/ 

_L-.50      ~  J_ 

iiiil 

iiii    iiiii 

im    illiiiili 

Considerable  flexibility  exists  in  steel  prices.  Not  only  do  steel  prices 
fluctuate  v/idely  but,  also,  prices  of  different  steel  products  fluctuate  in 
varying  degree  and  direction. 

As  compared  with  1924,  prices  of  steel  today  are  generally  lower,  whereas 
wage  rates  are  roughly  30%  higher. 


13796 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Reported  base  price  and  mill  net  yield — heavy  structural  shapes  at  Pittsburgh 
[Cents  per  pound] 


Base 
Price 

& 

Base 
Price 

Mill 
Yield 

Price 

Mill 
Yield 

1926 

May    .. 

1930 

Sep 

1934 

Jan     

1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.94 
2.00 
2.00 
2,00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 

1.81 
1.79 
1.81 
1.80 
1.78 
1.81 
1.82 
1.84 
1.85 

i.Si 
1.83 

1.73 
1.69 
1.65 
1.61 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 

1.68 
1.63 
1.61 
1.57 
1.52 
1.51 
1.51 
1.47 

1,80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 

Feb 

Oct. 

Mar 

Jul 

Nov       .- 

Dec 

May 

Sep 

Jan 

Feb 

Oct 

Jul 

Nov 

1935 

Aug 

Dec 

Sep 

Jan.. _ 

1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 

Oct  . 

1931 

1.74 

Nov 

Dec 

Mar 

1.78 

1.64 
1.65 
1.65 
1.65 
1.65 
1.65 
1.63 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.50 

1.47 
1.47 
1.5C 
1.50 
1.48 
1.49 
1.48 
1.46 
1.46 
1.44 
1.47 
1.46 

May.. 

1927 

Feb 

Jan 

1  75 

Mar 

Jul 

1  76 

1.98 
1.90 
1.90 
1.88 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.78 
1.75 
1.77 
1.80 

1.82 
1.83 
1.80 
1.81 
1.78 
1.76 
1.78 
1.73 
1.72 
1.71 
1.71 
1.71 

Apr 

Aug 

1  76 

Jan 

May ""' 

Sep 

1  74 

Feb 

Oct 

Mar 

Jul    . 

Nov 

Dec     

May'::"."::" 

Sep . 

Jan      . 

Oct 

Jul 

Nov 

1936 

Dec 

Sep.. 

1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 

1932 

1,74 

Feb . 

Mar... 

1.72 

1.60 
1.50 
1.52 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 

1.39 
1.37 
1.33 
1.35 
1.34 
1.36 
1.42 
1.37 
1.40 
1.44 
1.42 
1.47 

1.72 

May 

1928 

Feb 

Jun 

1  72 

Mar 

Jul 

1.71 

1.81 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 

1.74 
1.74 
1.76 
1.77 
1.75 
1.77 
1.77 
1.77 
1.77 
1.78 
1.80 
1.79 

Apr 

Aug 

1.73 

Jan 

May 

Sep 

1.77 

Feb 

Oct  "     " 

1.79 

Mar 

Jul    - 

Nov 

1.79 

Dec 

i^::::::::::: 

Sep 

Jan _ 

.Oct 

Jul 

Nov 

1937 

Aug 

Sep 

Dec 

Jan 

2.05 
2.05 
2.21 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 

Oct 

1933 

1.84 

Nov 

Feb. 

1.85 

Dec 

Mar... .- 

1.88 

1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 

1.45 
1.42 
1.46 
1.49 
1.46 
1.46 
1.46 
1.48 
1.55 
1.59 
1.63 
1.63 

Apr 

1.93 

May 

1929 

2.00 

Mar 

Jul 

2.10 

1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.95 
1.95 
1.95 
1.95 
1.95 
1.95 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 

1.80 
1.80 
1.79 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.79 
1.78 
1.78 
1.78 
1.76 

2.17 

Jan      . 

May 

Sep... 

2.19 

Feb 

Jun 

Oct . 

2.18 

Mar 

Jul 

Nov 

2.20 

Apr 

Aug 

Dec 

2.20 

May 

Sep 

Jan        

Jun 

Oct 

Jul  - 

Nov 

1938 

Dec 

Sep ::::::::::: 

Jan 

2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.22 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 

1934 

Feb 

2.14 

Dec 

Mar 

Apr 

2.18 

1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.74 
1.85 
1.85 
1.81 
1.80 

1.70 
1.67 
1.66 
1.68 
1.69 
1.70 
1.G9 
1.67 

2.16 

May 

1930 

2.12 

Mar 

Jul    

2.05 

1.83 

1.80 
1.80 
1.80 

1.77 
1.70 
1.71 
1.70 

2.02 

May  

Sep 

2.01 

Feb":":"":": 

Oct 

2.01 

Mar 

Jul 

Nov 

2.00 

Apr 

Aug 

Dec           .      - 

1.98 

Base  prices  are  as  rer)ortcd  by  Iron  Age  and  are  monthly  averages  of  weekly  figures. 

Mill  net  yield  is  an  average  of  yields  at  Clairton  and  Homestead  plants  of  U,  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidi- 
ary which  represent  net  sales  of  heavy  structural  shapes  to  domestic  market  (after  freight)  divided  by  num- 
ber of  tons  shipped,  converted  to  cents  per  pound. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  TOWER 


13797 


5 
4 

Q 

z      3 
o 

Q. 

Ul 
0. 

z 
o 

1 

REPORTED  BASE  PRICE  AND  MILL  NET  YIELD 

HEAVY  STRUCTURAL  SHAPES  AT  PITTSBURGH 

5 
4 

Q 

3      z 

■=> 
o 

Q- 
CC 
Q- 
2 

z 

( 

EPORT 

:d 

^7 

^ 

^ 

\= 

^ 

-^ 

\ 

^". 

■^ 

r.  "'O'**^^'  n 

y 

If^ 

r^ 

/ 

/ 

■^ 

^ 

s 

NET  YIELD 
jesioiARy) 

1926    1927     1928     1929    1930     1931     1932     1933     1934     1935     1935     1937     1938     1939     1940 

Base  prices  of  heavy  structural  shapes  at  Pittsburgh,  as  reported  by 
Iron  Age,  have  shov^n  considerable  flexibility  since  1 926. 
There  has  been  even  more  fluctuation  in  the  mill  net  yield,  that  is,  the 
amount  per  pound  actually  received  by  the  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidi- 
ary after  deduction  of  cost  of  delivery.  Such  mill  net  yield  declined  25% 
from  the  high  of  1929  to  the  low  of  1932.  The  Increases  In  prices  In  1937 
were  the  resolt  of  increased  wages  and  other  costs. 

Factors  tending  to  lower  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to  reported  base 
price  are  principally  (a)  reductions  from  base  price,  and  (b)  excess  of  actual 
cost  of  delivery  over  freight  added  to  base  price  in  computing  the 
delivered  price.  Factors  tending  to  raise  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to 
reported  base  price  are  principally  (a)  extras  for  special  finish,  quality,  size, 
heat  treatment,  etc.,  and  (b)  extras  for  small  quantity. 


13798  CONCKNTRATTON  OF  EOONOMTC  POWER 

Reported  base  price  and  7nill  net  yield — Heavy  structural  shapes  at  Chicago 
[Cents  per  pound] 


Base 
Price 

Mill 
Yield 

Base 
Price 

Mill 
Yield 

Base 
Price 

Mill 
Yield 

1926 

May -. 

1930 

Sep 

1934 

2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 

1.90 
1.87 
1.91 
1.90 
1.91 
1.91 
1.93 
1.93 
1.96 
1.95 
1.96 
1.97 

1.83 
1.79 
1.75 
1.75 
1.71 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 

1.75 
1.71 
1.70 
1.72 
1.65 
1.64 
1.64 
1.60 

1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 

1.79 

Feb 

Oct 

1.83 

Mm 

Jul 

Nov 

1.80 

Dec . 

Jan. 

1.85 

M^::::;:::::: 

Sep 

Jun. 

Oct 

Jul 

Nov... 

1935 

Aug 

Dec 

Sep 

Jan 

1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 

Oct 

1931 

1.86 

Feb 

1.85 

Mar.-- 

1.86 

1.71 
1.72 
1.70 
1.75 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.60 

1.67 
1.69 
1.70 
1.66 
1.69 
1.64 
1.68 
1.64 
1.63 
1.64 
1.62 

Apr 

1.85 

May 

1927 

Feb 

Jun 

1.86 

Mar 

Jul 

1.89 

2.10 
2.03 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
1.94 
1.90 
1.85 
1.87 
1.90 

1.92 
1.90 
1.93 
1.90 
1.90 
1.89 
1.87 
1.85 
1.85 
1.82 
1.79 
1.79 

Jan 

May 

Sep 

1.87 

Oct 

Mar 

Jul 

Nov 

1.86 

Dec 

1.83 

May 

Sep 

Jan 

Oct 

Jul 

Nov 

1936 

Aug 

Dec 

Sep _. 

Jan 

1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.95 
1.95 
1.95 
1.95 
1.95 
1.95 

1932 

Feb. 

1.85 

Dee 

Mar 

Apr 

1.84 

1.68 
1.65 
1.68 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 

1.59 
1.58 
1.60 
1.63 
1.66 
1.70 
1.65 
1.68 
1.65 
1.65 

1.84 

May 

1928 

Feb 

Jun 

1.83 

Mar 

Jul                 .  . 

1.84 

1.91 
1.95 
1.98 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 

1.89 
1.88 
1.88 
1.86 
1.85 
1.86 
1.84 
1.86 
1.84 
1.86 
1.87 
1.87 

1.87 

Jan 

May::::::::": 

Sep 

1.84 

Feb 

Oct 

1.90 

Mar  . 

Jul 

Nov 

1.91 

Anr 

Aug 

Dec 

1.93 

Xy::::::::::: 

Sep 

Jan 

Jun 

Oct 

Jul 

Nov 

1937 

Aug 

Sep 

Dec 

Jan..  . 

2.10 
2.10 
2.25 
2.20 
2.30 
2.30 
2.30 
2.30 
2.30 
2.30 
2.30 
2.30 

1933 

Nov 

Feb 

1.94 

Dec 

Mar 

1.96 

1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.77 
1.70 
1.70 
1.69 
1.65 
1.75 
1.75 
1.76 

1.63 
1.62 
1.63 

L59 
1.54 
1.53 
1.60 
1.63 
1.69 
1.71 
1.75 

2.04 

May 

1929 

Feb 

2.05 

Mar 

Jul 

2.12 

2.00 
2.01 
2.05 
2.05 
2.05 
2.05 
2.05 
2.05 
2.05 
2.03 
2.00 
2.00 

L94 

l!91 
1.90 
1.88 
1.89 
1.91 
1.90 
1.88 
1.87 
1.83 

May 

Aug 

2.  16 

Jan 

Sep 

2.21 

Feb 

Jun 

Oct . 

2.28 

Mar 

Jul 

Nov 

2.29 

Dec 

2.32 

May 

Sep 

Jan 

Jun! 

Oct.... 

Jul 

Nov.. 

1938 

Aug 

Dec 

Sep 

Jan 

2.30 
2.30 
2.30 
2.30 
2.30 
2.26 
?.  10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 

Oct 

1934 

2.32 

Nov 

Feb 

2.29 

Dec 

Mar 

2.31 

1.76 
1.75 
1.75 
1.75 
1.90 
1.90 
1.86 
1.85 

1.80 
1.78 
1.80 
1.80 
1.81 
1.81 
1.84 
1.81 

2.25 

May 

1930 

Feb 

Jun 

2.24 

Mar 

Apr 

Jul 

2.14 

1.99 
1.95 
1.94 
1.90 

1.84 
1.82 
1.79 
1.79 

Aug            .  ... 

2.11 

Jan 

May 

Sep 

2.12 

Feb 

Jun 

Jul 

Oct 

2.09 

Mar 

Nov 

2.12 

Aug 

Dec 

2.11 

Base  prices  are  f»s  reporteil  by  Iron  Age  and  are  monlbly  averages  of  weekly  figures. 

Mill  net  yield  Is  that  of  South  Cliicago  pluut  of  V.  S.  Stt't-i  Corixiratiou  subshiiHry,  and  represents  net 
SHies  of  heuvy  structural  shapes  to  donie.sllc  iimrkel  (after  fril(dit)  divided  l>y  iiuinbcr  o(  loiis  slapped, 
•-■ouverteil  tn  twuts  iicr  pound. 


C()NCt:NTliATlUN  OF  ECONOMIC  I'OWER 


13799 


5 

4 

^      3 
o 

Q. 

a: 
a. 

z 

LJ 
O 

REPORTED  BASE  PRICE  MID  MILL  NET  YIELD 

HEAVY  STRUCTURAL  SHAPES  AT  CHICAGO 

5 

4 

Q 

a: 

0. 

z 

U) 

O 

1 

\ 

# . 

REF 

noTrn 

■7 

\. 

^ 

^BASE  PRIC 
■NAdRON  AGE) 

a 

^ 

rf 

i 

ty^ 

V. 

ILL  NE 

T  YIEL 

D 

SUBS 

1926     1927     1928    1929     1930     1931     1932     1933     1934     1935     1936    1937     1938     1939     1940 

Base  prices  of  heavy  structural  shapes  at  Chicago,  as  reported  by  Iron  Age, 
have  shown  considerable  flexibility  since  1926. 

There  has  been  even  more  fluctuation  In  the  mill  net  yield,  1.  e,,  the  amount 
per  pound  actually  received  by  the  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiary  after 
deduction  of  cost  of  delivery.  Such  mill  net  yield  declined  24%  from  the 
high  of  1929  to  the  low  of  1933.  The  Increases  in  prices  In  1937  were  the 
result  of  Increased  wages  and  other  costs. 

Factors  tending  to  lower  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to  reported  baie  price 
are  principally  (a)  deductions  from  base  price  and  (b)  excess  of  actual  cost 
of  delivery  over  freight  added  to  base  price  In  computing  delivered  price. 
Factors  tending  to  raise  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to  reported  base  price 
are  principally  (a)  extras  for  special  finish,  quality,  sI-t,  heat  treatment, 
etc,  and  (b)  extras  for  small  quantity. 


13800       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Reported  base  price  and  mill  net  yield — Plates  at  Pittsburgh 
[Cents  per  pound] 


MiU 
Net 
Yield 


1.86 
1.85 
1.85 
1.84 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.78 
1.75 
1.77 
1.80 


1.81 
1.85 
1,85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 


1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.95 
1.95 
1.95 
1.95 
1.95 
1.95 
1.94 
1.90 
1.90 


1.75 
1.76 
1.75 
1.75 
1.77 
1.77 
1.84 
1.85 
1.85 
1.86 
1.84 


1.82 
I;  79 
1.76 
1.75 
1.73 
1.74 
1.70 
1.71 
1.72 
1.70 
1.73 


1.73 
1.75 
1.74 
1.73 


1.70 
1.73 
1.74 
1.73 


1.75 
1.75 
1.76 
1.75 
1.77 
1.77 
1.79 
1.70 


1.70 
1.69 
1.70 
1.68 


May 
Jun. 
Jul- 
Aug- 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul-. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 

>    .V. 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr- 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug- 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov- 
Dec. 


Jan., 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul- 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov- 
Dec 


Jan. . 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 


Mill 
Net 
Yield 


1.73 
1.69 
1.65 
1.61 
1.60 


1.64 
1.65 
1.65 
1.65 
1.65 
1.65 


1.52 
1.60 
1,60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 


1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.55 
1.50 
1.53 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 


1.52 
1.53 
1.48 
1.47 
1.47 
1.50 


1.51 
1.49 
1.43 
1.43 
1.42 
1.40 
1.39 
1.40 
1.43 
1  40 
1.38 
1.38 


1.34 
1.33 
1.36 
1.32 
1.40 
1.34 
1.36 
1.34 
1.37 
1.41 
1.47 


1.36 
1.31 
1.32 
1.33 
1.33 
1.42 
1.52 
1.55 
1.59 


1.70 

1.73 

1.70 

1.72 

1.70 

1.72 

V74 

1,77 

1,85 

1.75 

1.85 

1.77 

1.81 

1.80 

1.80 

1.84 

Oct. 
Nov 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mer. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.- 
Aug- 
Sep- 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec- 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan., 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan., 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct., 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Mill 
Net 
Yield 


1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.80 


1.80 
1.80 
1.80 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 


2,05 
2.05 
2.21 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 


2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.22 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 


Base  prices  are  as  reported  by  Iron  Age  and  are  monthly  averages  of  weekly  figures. 

Mill  net  yield  is  that  of  Homestead  plant  of  U.  S.  Steef  Corporation  subsiiiiarj  and  represents  net  sales 
of  sheared  plates  to  domestic  market  (after  freight)  divided  by  number  of  tons  shipped,  converted  to  cents 
per  pound. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13801 


5 
4 

?     3 

2 

a. 
^      2 

z 

UJ 

O 

1 

REPORTED  BASE  PRICE  AND  MILL  NET  YIELD 

PLATES  AT  PinSBURGH 

5 
4 

3  i 

o 

OL 

a: 

Q. 

2      CO 

z 

LU 

o 

1 

/7 

^ 

^ 

^ 

*'\/- 

-^ 

\ 

REPOR 
BASEP 

(IRON 

n 

TED 

RICE, 

f 

^ 

^ 

y 

^ 

^ 

IM'' 

ILLNE 

ITOU 
SUBS 

7YIEL 
ssc. 

) 

1926     1927     1928     1929    1930     1931     1932     1933    1934     1935     1936    1937     1938     1939     1940 

Base  prices  of  plates,  as  reported  by  Iron  Age.  have  shown  considerable 
flexibility  since  1926. 

There  has  been  even  more  fluctuation  In  the  mill  net  yield,  that  is,  the 
amount  per  pound  actually  received  by  the  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidi- 
ary after  deduction  of  cost  of  delivery..  Such  mill  net  yield  declined  32%. 
from  the  high  of  1929  to  the  low  of  1933.  The  increases  in  prices  in  1937 
v/ere  the  result  of  increased  wages  and  other  costs. 

.Factors  tending  to  lower  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to  reported  base 
price  are  principally  (a)  reductions  from  base  price,  and  (b)  excess  of  actual 
cost  of  delivery  over  freight  added  to  base  price  In  computing  the 
delivered  price.  Factors  tending  to  raise  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to 
reported  base  price  are  principally  (a)  extras  for  special  finish,  quality,  size, 
heat  treatment,  etc..  and  (b)  extras  for  small  quantity. 


13802  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Reported  base  price  and  mill  net  yield — Bars  at  Pittsburgh 
[Cents  per  pound] 


2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
1.95 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 


1.89 
1.85 
1.85 
1.79 


1.92 
1.92 
1.93 


1.96 
1.96 
1.95 


1.93 

l!90 
1.89 
1.84 


1.77 
1.77 
1.76 


1.80 
1.80 
1.81 
1.80 
1.82 
1.81 
1.83 
1.84 
1.86 
1.85 


May 
Jun. 
JuL- 
Aug 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 

Feb 

Mar. 

Apr. 

May 

Jun. 

Jul.- 

Aug. 

Sep. 

Oct. 

Nov. 

Dec. 


Jan.- 
Feb-. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May. 
Jun.. 
Jul... 
Aug.. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
No\\^ 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug 


Mill 
Price      Yield 


1.75 
1.73 
1.65 
1.64 
1.61 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 


1.64 
1.62 
1.60 
1.56 
1.55 


1.64 

1.55 

1.65 

1.57 

1.65 

1.57 

1.65 

1.55 

1.65 

1.54 

1.65 

1.50 

1.63 

1.49 

1.60 

1.50 

1.60 

1.46 

1.60 

1.49 

1.60 

1.46 

1.58 

1.47 

1.50 
1.50 
1.52 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 
1.60 


1.46 
1.40 
1.45 
1.47 
1.45 
1.45 
1.48 
1.45 
1.51 
1.50 
1.52 
1.45 


1.48 
1.50 
1.47 
1.51 
1.38 
1.43 
1.42 
1.43 
1.49 
1.51 
1.52 


1.75 
1.75 
1.75 
1.79 
1.90 
1.90 
1.82 


1.73 
1.75 
1.71 
1.80 
1.81 
1.81 
1.81 
1.85 


Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov 
Dec 


Jan. 
Feb 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul  . 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb- 
Mar. 
Apr- 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug- 
Sep. 
Oct., 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec- 


Base       Mill 
Price      Yield 


1.80 

1.81 

1.80 

1.84 

1  80 

1.84 

1.80 

1.85 

1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.95 
1.95 
1.97 
2.05 
2.05 
2.05 


2.20 
2.20 
2.40 
2.45 
2.45 
2.45 
2.45 
2.45 
2.45 
2.45 
2.45 
2.45 


2.45 
2.45 
2.45 
2.45 
2.45 
2.41 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 


Base  prices  are  as  reported  by  Iron  Age  and  are  monthly  averages  of  weekly  figures. 

Mill  net  yield  is  that  of  Duquesne  plant  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiary  and  represents  net  sales 
ofbars,  rounds,  etc.,  O.  H.,  to  domestic  market  (after  freight)  divided  by  number  of  tons  shipped,  converted 
to  cents  per  pound. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13803 


REPORTED  BASE  PRICE  AND  MILL  NET  YIELD 


BARS  AT  PITTSBURGH 


r 

7 

\ 

Ji> 

K 

^ 

'^ 

1 

=^ 

REPO 
BAS£ 

WON 

tTEO 

J^ 

-* 

4 

/       , 

> 

V* 

laN 

if 

) 

1926    1927    1928    1929    1930    1931    1932    1933    1934    193S    1^6    1937    1938    1939    1940 


Base  prices  of  bars  at  Pittsburgh,  as  reported  by  Iron  Age.  have  shown  con- 
siderable flexibility  since  1926. 

■  There  has  been  even  more  fluctuation  in  the  mill  net  yield,  that  is,  the 
amount  per  pound  actually  received  by  the  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  sub- 
sidiary after  deduction  of  cost  of  delivery.  Such  mill  net  yield  declined 
n°la  from  the  high  of  1929  to  the  low  of  1933.  The  increases  in  prices  in 
1937  were  the  result  of  increased  wages  and  other  costs. 

Factors  tending  to  lower  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to  reported  base 
price  are  principally  (a)  reductions  frorp  base  price,  (b)  excess  of  actual 
cost  of  delivery  over  freight  added  to  base  price  in  computing  the 
delivered  price,  and  (c)  quantity  discounts.  Factors  tending  to  raise  mill 
net  yield  with  respect  to  reported  I-  ase  price  are  principally  (a)  extras  for 
special  finish,  quality,  size,  heat  treatment,  etc.,  and  (b)  extras  for  small 
quantity. 


124491— 41-^pt.  26 IE 


13804  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Reported  base  price  and  mill  net  yield — bars  at  Chicago 
[Cents  per  pound] 


Mill 
Net 
Yield 


2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 
2.10 


2.10 
2.03 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 


1.91 
1.95 
1.98 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 
2.00 


2.00 
2.01 
2.05 
2.05 
2.06 
2.06 
2.05, 
2.05 
2.05 
2.03 
2.00 
2.00 


1.99 
1.95 
1.96 
1.91 


2.08 
2.09 
2.08 
2.08 
2.06 
2.09 
2.09 
2.11 
2.12 
2.10 
2.13 
2.12 


2.13 
2.06 
2.06 
2.04 
2.03 
2.05 
2.00 

l!96 
1.93 
1.96 


1.97 
2.00 
2.01 
2.00 
2.03 
2.02 
2.03 
2.03 
2.04 


2.05 
2.06 
2.04 
2.04 
2.03 
2.03 
2.04 
2.05 
2.03 
2.03 
1.99 
1.99 


1.96 
1.93 
1.94 
1.93 


May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec- 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep., 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec- 


Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan... 
Feb... 
Mar., 
Apr... 
Mny.. 
Jun... 
Jul-... 
Aug... 


Mill 
Net 
Yield 


1.85 

1.83 

1.76 

1.76 

1.71 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.71 
1.72 
1.70 
1.75 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.70 
1.60 


1.68 

1.65 

1.68 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.70 

1.69 

1.65 

L80 

1.80 

1.80 

1.80 

1.95 

1.80 

2.00 

1,80 

1.97 

1.84 

2.00 

1.»ft 

1.97 

1.95 

1.95 

1.87 

1.97 

1.85 

2.00 

Oct. 
Nov 
Dec- 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep., 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Base 
Price 


MUl 
Net 
Yield 


1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 


1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.85 
1.90 
1.90 
1.90 


1.90 

1.90 

1.90 

1.90 

1.90 

1.90 

2.00 

2.00 

2.(K) 

2 

2.10 

2 

2.10 

2. 

2.10 

2. 

2.25 
2.25 
2.45 
2.50 
2.50 
2.50 
2.50 
2.50 
2.50 
2.50 
2.50 
2.50 


2.60 
2.50 
2.50 
2.50 
2.50 
2.45 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.25 
2.26 
2.25 


Base  prices  are  as  reported  by  Iron  Age  and  are  monthly  averages  of  weekly  figures. 

Mill  net  yield  is  that  of  Gary  plant  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiary  and  represents  net  sales  of  bars, 
rounds,  etc.,  O.  H.,  to  domestic  market  (after  freight)  divided  by  number  of  tons  shipped,  converted  to  cents 
per  pound;  classification  broadened  January,  1934. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13805 


REPORTED  BASE  PRICE  AND  MILL  NET  YIELD 

BARS  AT  CHICAGO 


-^ 

»^ 

V-, 

'"'■ 

M,^ 

NET  YIELD 
us.at 

y 

//' 

\ 

\: 

^■■- 

\ 

3«^ 

,  y 

■^    REPORTE 

) 

6<«/w 

v/ 

<n 

»N*Ot 

1926    1927    1928    1929    1930    1931    1932 


1934    1935    1936    1937    1933    )S39    1940 


Base  prices  of  bars  at  Oittago,  as  reported  by  'ron  Age,  have  shown  con- 
siderable flexibility  since  1926. 

There  has  been  even  more  fluctuation  in  the  mill  net"  yield,  that  is,  the 
annount  per  pound  actually  received  by  the  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  after 
deduction  of  cost  of  delivery.  Such  mill  net  yield  declined  22  7o  f""©"!  ^^^ 
high  of  1929  to  the  low  of  1932.  The  increases  in  prices  in  1937  were  the 
result  of  increased  wages  and  other  costs. 

Factors  tending  to  lower  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to  reported  bise 
price  ate  principally  (a)  reductions  from  base  price,  (b)  excess  of  actual 
cost  of  delivery  over  freight  added  to  base  price  in  computing  the 
delivered  price,  and  (c)  quantity  discounts.  Factors  tending  to  raise  mill  net 
yield  with  respect  to  reported  base  price  are  principally  (a)  extras  for  spe- 
cial finish,  quality,  size,  heat  treatment,  etc.,  and  (b)  extras  for  small 
quantity. 


13806 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Reported  base  price  and  mill  net  yield— standard  black  welded  pipe  at  Pittsburgh 
[Dollars  per  gross  ton] 


Base 
Price 

Mill 
Net 
Yield 

Base 
Price 

Mill 
Net 
Yield 

Base 
Price 

MUl 
Net 
Yield 

1926 

May 

1930 

Sep 

1934 

78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78. 74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 

83.59 
82.41 
81.71 
87.70 
82.46 
83.46 
81.51 
81.73 
82.05 
82.43 
81.90 
79.43 

74.48 
74.48 
74.48 
74.48 
74.48 
74.48 
74.48 
74.48 

74.99 
73.22 
74.96 
74.38 
75.00 
74.01 
73.83 
70.89 

76.61 
76.61 
76.61 
76.61 

73.34 

Oct. 

72.09 

Jul- - 

Nov 

72.65 

Dec 

72.64 

May 

Sep. 

Jan 

Oct 

Ftil 

Nov 

1935 

Dec 

Bep 

Jan 

76.61 
76.61 
76.61 
76.61 
76.61 
76.61 
76.61 
76.61 
76.61 
76.61 
76.61 
76.61 

Oct 

1931 

73.17 

Feb 

74.18 

Mar. 

73.12 

74.48 
74.48 
74.48 
74.48 
71.22 
72.62 
72.62 
72.62 
72.62 
72.62 
72.62 
72.62 

73.54 
74.26 
74.18 
73.39 
69.66 
69.90 
70.48 
71.66 
71.78 
70.16 
70.74 
71.42 

Apr 

72.91 

May 

1927 

73.34 

Mar -- 

Jul.. 

73.02 

78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
76.76 
74.80 
74.80 

83.36 
82.11 
83.02 
82.95 
83.62 
82.40 
81.12 
81.19 
80.93 
78.29 
75.75 
77.10 

72.92 

May. ..-. 

Sep. 

72.62 

^eb "" 

Jun 

Oct 

71.43 

Mar 

Jul 

Nov 

74.14 

tKy : 

Aug 

Dec 

73.36 

Sep 

Jan ,. 

Feb - 

Jun 

Oct 

Jul 

Nov 

1936 

Aug 

Dec 

Sep     ..  

Jan 

76.61 
72.78 
69.22 
68.32 
68.32 
68.32 
68.32 
68.32 
68.32 
68.32 
68.32 
68.32 

Oct 

1932 

73.19 

71.90 

Mar 

67.45 

72.62 
72.62 
72.62 
72.62 
72.62 
72.62 
72.62 
72.62 
72.80 
72.80 
72.80 
72.80 

72.21 
68.64 

70'.  16 
66.88 
70.49 
68.43 
68.83 
68.82 
68.22 
68.64 
65.25 

Apr--- ---. 

62.30 

1928 

May 

65.17 

65.96 

Mar     . 

Jul 

64.70 

76.83 
76.83 
76.83 
78.27 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 

78.60 
78.11 
78.47 
78.00 
78.12 
80.47 
80.21 
80.31 
80.63 
79.48 
80.42 
80.11 

65.19 

Jan 

May                 : 

Sep 

65.86 

Feb 

Jun ^ 

Jul ^. 

Aug 

Oct 

64.57 

Mar 

Nov 

64.39 

Apr 

Dec 

65.11 

May 

Sep 

Jan 

Jim 

Oct 

jSl 

Nov 

1937 

Dec 

Sep 

Jan 

68.32 
68.32 
77.82 
79. 52 
79.52 
79.52 
79.52 
79.52 
79.52 
79.52 
79.52 
79.52 

Oct 

1933 

66.18 

Mnv 

Feb 

65.99 

DM          

Mar 

65.27 

72.80 
72.80 
72.80 
64.96 
64.96 
69.96 
69.16 
69.16 
69.16 
69.16 
69.16 
69.16 

68.36 
69.39 
68.14 
60.07 
50.63 
63.46 
61.12 
60.43 
64.49 
65.97 
65.38 
64.73 

Apr -- 

72.38 

1929 

;May 

75.96 

Feb 

70.41 

Mar....- 

Jul-- -. 

73.41 

78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
78.74 

79.47 
79.61 
78.33 
80.37 
79.34 
78.11 
79.29 
79.26 
77.52 
79.02 
80.75 
79.87 

73:13 

May  - 

Sep 

74.45 

Jun 

Jul 

Oct 

74.70 

Mar     . 

Nov 

72.52 

Dec 

71.74 

uiy :" 

Sep 

Jan 

Oct 

Jul.             

Nov- 

1938 

Dec 

Sep 

Jan 

79.52 
79.52 
79.52 
79.52 
79.52 
79.52 
70.56 
70.56 
7a  56 
70.56 
70.56 
70.56 

Oct 

1934 

76.96 

Feb 

73.58 

Mar 

75.56 

69.16 
69.16 
69.16 
71.02 
76.61 
76.61 
76.61 
76.61 

66.80 
67.78 
66.34 
66.33 
67.95 
66.42 
73.93 
74.44 

Apr 

75.59 

1930 

Feb 

jSn  

75.11 

Mar 

jSi  .::::::::::: 

66.76 

78.74 
78.74 
78.74 
74.48 

78.56 
79.63 
79.14 
70.89 

66.00 

Jan 

May 

Sep 

65.58 

Feb 

Jun 

Oct :::  

67.32 

Jul. 

Nov 

66.60 

Dec 

66.70 

1 

Base  prices  are  as  reported  by  Iron  Age  (converted  to  a  gross  ton  basis)  and  are  monthly  averages  o(  weekly 
figures. 

Mill  net  yield  is  that  of  National  plant  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiary  and  represents  net  sales 
of  standard  black  welded  pipe  to  domestic  market  (after  freight)  divided  by  number  of  tons  shipped.  This 
classification  of  pipe  includes  some  pipe  sold  on  a  base  diflerent  from  the  base  price  to  which  the  mill  net 
yield  is  here  compared,  but  the  two  base  prices  show  the  same  general  trends  and  fluctuations. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13807 


REPORTED  BASE  PRICE  AND  MILL  NET  YIELD 

STANDARD  BUCK  WELDED  PIPE  AT  PIHSBURGH 


1 

^ 

rs 

REPORl 

ED 

-^ 

"h 

fV 

BsT"' 

IRON  AGE)  rr; 

r^-~>A 

\__ 

If^ 

i 

V-i 

1^ 

\z 

a 

u 

UMILL  Na  YIELD 
1      (TO  u.s.sc. 

I          SUBSIDIARY) 

^0     A 


1926    1927    1928    1929    1930    1931    1932    1933    1934    1935    1936    1937    1938    1939     1940 


Base  prices  of  standard  black  welded  pipe,  as  reported  by  Iron  Age,  have 
shown  considerable  flexibility  since  1926. 

There  has  been  even  more  fluctuation  in  the  mill  net  yield,  i.  e..  the  amount 
per  ton  actually  received  by  the  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiary  after 
deduction  of  cost  of  delivery.  After  decreasing  gradually  from  1926  to 
1929,  the  mill  net  yield  declined  37%  from  the  high  of  1929  to  the  low  of 
1933.  The  Increases  in  prices  in  1937  were  the  result  of  increased  wages 
and  other  costs. 

Factors  tending  to  lower  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to  reported  base  price 
are  principally  (a)  reductions  from  base  price,  (b)  excess  of  actual  cost  of 
delivery  over  freight  added  to  base  price  in  computing  the  delivered  price, 
(c)  quantity  discounts  and  (d)  deductions  for  quality,  size,  etc.  Factors  tend- 
ing to  raise  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to  reported  base  price  are  principally 
(a)  extras  for  special  finish,  quality,  size,  steel  treatment,  etc.,  and  (b)  extras 
for  small  quantity. 


13808 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Reported  base  price  and  mill  net  yield — cold  rolled  sheets 
[Cents  per  pound] 


Base 
Price 

MiU 
Yield 

Base 
Price 

MiU 
Yield 

Base 
Price 

Mill 
Yield 

1926 

May 

1930 

Sep 

1934 

Jan 

4.45 
4.38 
4.35 
4.28 
4.24 
4.15 
4.15 
4.15 
4.25 
4.25 
4.25 
4.25 

■4.61 

3.75 
3.66 
3.60 
3.60 
3.50 
3.45 
3.38 
3.30 

'3.68 

2.95 
2.95 
2.95 
2.95 

3  28 

Feb 

June 

Oct 

3.38 

Mar " 

Jul 

Nov 

Dec  . 

3.34 

3.39 

MaV::::::::::: 

Sep 

Jan 

Feb 

Jim..      .      . 

Oct 

JuL 

Nov 

1935 

Dec 

Sep... 

Jan 

2.95 
2.95 
2.95 
2.95 
2.95- 
2.95 
2.95 
2.95 
2.95 
2.95 
2.95 
2.95 

Ort 

1931 

3.26 

3.10 

Dec 

Mar 

3.18 

3.30 
3.90 
3.24 
3.10 
3.03 
3.02 
3.10 
3.10 
3.10 
3.10 
3.10 
3.02 

'3.12 

Apr 

3.17 

May 

1927 

Feb 

Jun 

3.36 

Mar 

Jul 

3.24 

4.18 
4.15 
4.15 
4.15 
4.15 
4.25 
4.26 
4.25 
4.25 
4.16 
4.12 
4.00 

'4.41 

Apr 

Aug 

Sep            .  .  . 

3.27 

Ian 

May """■ 

3.27 

Feb 

Oct         

3.27 

Mar 

Jul 

Nov 

3.10 

Aug.. 

Dec 

Jan 

3.06 

t/ay.:::::::::: 

Sep... 

Jun 

Oct 

1936 

Jul 

Nov 

Aug 

Dec 

2.95 
2.95 
2.95 
2.95 
2.95 
2.95 
3.05 
3.05 
3.05 
3.05 
3.05 
3.25 

sep^.v.v:::::::: 

Jan , 

Feb 

3.0O 

Oct 

1932 

Feb 

2.93 

Nov 

Mar 

2.85 

Dec 

2.90 
2.80 
2.86 
2.90 
2.89 
2.85 
2.85 
2.81 
2.75 
2.66 
2.63 
2.65 

'3.07 

Apr 

2.85 

May 

3.05 

1928 

Mar 

JuL. 

3.07 

4.00 
4.08 
4.15 
4.04 
4.00 
4.00 
4.00 
4.00 
4.00 
4.00 
4.00 
4.08 

•4.09 

3.15 

Jan         

May 

Sep.... 

3.15 

Feb 

Oct : 

3.13 

Mar 

Jul 

Nov 

3.17 

Apr 

Aug 

Dec 

3.08 

Npay-":::::::::: 

Sep.. 

Jan 

un 

Oct 

1937 

Jul 

Nov 

Dec... 

3.25 
3.25 
3.49 
3.55 
3.55 
3.55 
3.55 
3.55 
3.55 
3.55 
3.55 
3.55 

Sep 

Jan 

3.00 

Oct 

Feb 

3.12 

1933 

Nov 

Mar            

3.27 

Dec 

2.35 
2.25 
2.30 
2.30 
2.34 
2.29 
2.40 
2.47 
2.76 
2.75 
2.75 
2.76 

■2.66 

Apr    

3.35 

May 

3.48 

1929 

Feb 

Jun 

3.67 

Mar 

Jul - 

3.63 

4.10 
4.10 
4.10 
4.10 
4.10 
4.10 
4.10 
4.08 
4.00 
4.00 
4.00 
3.98 

'4.23 

Apr 

Aug 

3.54 

Jan 

May 

Sep 

3.52 

Feb 

Oct             

3.58 

Mar     

Jul 

Nov 

3.54 

Dec. 

3.61 

i^y::::::::::: 

Sep 

Jan 

Jun 

Oct 

1938 

jSi 

Nov 

Dec 

3.55 
3.60 
3.45 
3.46 
•     3.50 
3.35 
3.35 
3.35 
3.35 
3.23 
3.36 
3.35 

Sep 

Jan 

3.54 

Oct 

1934 

Feb 

3.36 

Nov 

Mar          

3.35 

Dec 

2.75 
2.75 
2.75 
2.85 
3.16 
3.16 
2.99 
2.95 

2.88 
3.17 
3.06 
3.08 
3.23 
3.16 
3.27 
3.25 

Apr 

3.24 

May 

3.38 

1930 

Feb 

Jun 

3.32 

M^v.v.v.".".:::: 

jS^v.".::::::::: 

3.12 

3.90 
3.90 
3.88 
3,80 

'3.68 

Apr 

Aug           

3.08 

Jan 

Sfay 

Sep 

2.97 

Feb 

Oct 

2.78 

Mar 

Jul 

Nov 

2.67 

Apr 

Aug 

Dae.   . 

2.69 

'  Yearly  average. 

Base  prices  are  as  reported  by  Iron  Age  and  are  monthly  averages  o(  weekly  figures.  Iron  Age  data  are 
for  20-gauge  cold  rolled  sheets  at  Pittsburgh  from  September  1926  to  April  1938;  data  prior  and  subsequent 
to  that  period  have  been  adjusted  to  that  gauge. 

Mill  net  yield  is  a  weighted  average  of  yields  of  plants  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries,  which  repre- 
sents net  sales  of  cold  rolled  and  automobile  sheets  to  domestic  market  (after  freight)  divided  by  number 
of  tons  shipped,  converted  .to  cent?  poi  pound.  Dataarefor  plants  of  American  Sheet  and  Tin  Plate  Com- 
pany prior  to  1937,  and  thereafter  for  Vandergrift  and  Oary  plants  of  Carnegie- Illinois  Steel  Corporation. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13809 


REPORTED  BASE  PI^ICE  AND  MILL  NET  YIELD 


COLD  ROLLED  SHEETS 


'\y- 

> 

>— 

:^ 

NETY 
3  US  S. 

BSIDWR 

K 

u 

-^^ 

MILL 

<T 

S 

ELD 

r 

\ 

REPORTED 
BASE  PRICE 

(IRON  AG£I 

■s 

y 

•J- 

\F 

\ 

1926    1927    1928    1929    1930    1931    1932    1933    1934    1935    1936    1937    1938     1939    1940 


Base  prices  of  cold-rolled  sheets,  as  reported  by  Iron  Age,  have  declined  considerably 
since  1926  as  well  as  having  shown  considerable  fluctuation  during  the  period. 
The  monthly  mill  net  yield,  i.  e.,  the  amount  per  pound  received  by  the  U.  S.  Steel 
Corporation  subsidiary  after  deduction  of  cost  of  delivery,  has  shown  even  more 
fluctuation  than  the  published  base  price.  The  mill  net  yield  curve  prior  to  1 934  appears 
to  fluctuate  less  than  the  reported  base  price  because  it  is  based  on  annual  averages, 
monthly  data  not  being  available. 

Over  the  period  the  mill  net  yield  has  declined  from  an  average  of  4.6  K  per  poijnd  in 
1926  to  a  l938  1owof2.67(;  per  pound,  a  decrease  of  42%. 

Factors  tending  to  lower  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to  reported  base  price  are  princi- 
pally (a)  reductions  from  base  price,  (b)  excess  of  actual  ccst  of  delivery  over  freight 
added  to  base  price  in  computing  the  delivered  price,  (c)  quantity  discounts  and  (d) 
deductions  for  quality,  size,  etc.  Factors  'ending  to  raise  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to 
reported  base  price  are  principally  (a)  extras  for  special  finish,  quality,  size,  heat  treat- 
ment, etc.,  and  (b)  extras  for  small  quantity. 


13810       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Reported  composite  price  and  composite  mill  net  yield 
[1926=1001 


Com- 
posite 
Price 


Mill 
Net 
Yield 


100.3 

99 

100.0 

100 

100.3 

99 

100.1 

100 

99.6 

100 

99,7 

fi9 

100.0 

99 

1(X).0 

99 

1(10.0 

99 

100.0 

99 

100.0 

99 

100.0 

99 

98.5 
95.9 
96.5 
96.2 
95.7 
95.5 
95.4 
96.4 
96.0 
93.0 
92.1 
92.1 

98.7 

b 

98.0 

97.0 

r 

96.6 

ay 

95.9 

n 

96.4 

96.3 

96.3 

96.9 

94.9 

95.2 

93.6 

1928 

92.3 
93.7 
94.1 
94.0 
93.0 
93.0 
92.6 
93.3 
93.3 
93.7 
94.2 
94.5 

93.4 

b 

93.4 

93.3 

r 

93.4 

94.3 

93.8 

92.9 



92.4 

p 

92.7 

92.9 

93.9 

93.7 

1929 

94.7 
94.7 
94.7 
96.0 
96.2 

96!  2 
95.6 
95.4 
94.9 
94.7 
95.2 

94.2 

b 

94.2 

ar 

93.9 

94.2 

94.3 

95  0 

ig 

95.4 

p 

94.5 

94.3 

94.3 

3C 

94  0 

1930 

93.4 
92.8 
92.7 
90.6 

88:2 

b 

91.6 

ar 

91  2 

pr 

89.9 

n 

88.0 

Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov 
Oec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr- 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul., 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec 


Jan. . 
Feb.. 
Mar. 
Apr.. 
May. 
Jun.. 
Jul... 
Aug.. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Com- 
posite 
Price 


Mill 
Net 
Yield 


87.2 
86.3 
85.9 
85.6 
85.4 
84.8 


86.6 
86.0 
85.0 
83.7 
83.3 
82.0 


85.4 
85.6 
85.6 
85.3 
85.3 
84.8 
84.4 
84.0 
84.0 
84.0 
83.8 
82.5 


82.2 
83.2 
82.3 
81.8 
81.4 


80.0 
81.3 
80.2 


81.2 
81.1 
81.2 
82.4 
82.4 
82.4 
82.7 
82.7 
82.7 
82.5 
82.0 
82.0 


81.4 
80.9 
80.6 
78.5 
77.8 
78.6 
81.1 
81.3 
81.6 
84.2 
83.5 
84.0 


78.6 
79.1 
79.3 
78.7 
77.7 
79.2 
79.5 
79.3 
79.0 
78.8 


77.0 
76.0 
76.6 
75.0 
74.5 
74.6 
73.5 
75.0 
77.2 
79.4 
82.6 
83.5 


87.4 
91.8 
92.9 
91.9 
93.3 
92.5 
89.9 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul-. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb.. 
Mar.. 
Apr.- 
May. 


Com-  Mill 
posite  Net 
Price      Yield 


88.8 
88.8 
88.8 


87.8 
90.3 
90.3 
90.5 
91.4 
91.4 
95.0 


108.5 

105.4 

108.5 

105.1 

108. 5 

105.9 

1(»S.  5 

104.3 

108.3 

104.4 

106.2 

102.7 

99.4 

97.9 

99.4 

96.2 

99.0 

95.9 

97.4 

93.7 

98.7 

91.6 

98.7 

92.2 

98.7 
98.7 
98.7 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER        13811 

Reported  composite  price  and  composite  mill  net  yield — Continued 
11926=100] 


Com-        Mill 
posite        Net 
Price       Yield 

Com-        Mill 
posite        Net 
Price       Yield 

Com-       Mill 
posite      Net 
Price      Yield 

1939 

Jul 

96  6  1        91  4 

Aug 

Sep 

Oct 

Nov 

The  reported  composite  price  index  Ls  based  upon  the  Iron  Age  composite  price,  which  is  an  arithmetic 
average  of  the  reported  base  prices  of  eight  representative  finished  steel  products. 

The  composite  mill  net  yield  index  represents  the  amount,  relative  to  that  for  1926,  received  per  ton  by 
U.  8.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  (after  freight)  from  sales  of  a  representative  constant  assortment  of  all 
principal  products. 


REPORTED  COMPOSITE  PRICE  AND  COMPOSITE  MILL  NET  YIELD 

1926  =  100 


COMP 

OSITE  PRICE 

"X 

^ 

*s»«. 

\ 

NTI 

^ 

-      r^f 

rn 

'"'•!»< 

A 

V 

\ 

^ 

cT 

"^ 

^, 

(TOU 
SUBSI 

OSITE 
TYIEL 
S.S.C. 
lARIES) 

D 

100    s 


1926  1927  1928  1929  1930  1931  1932  1933  1934  1935  1936  1937  1938  1939  1940 


Base  prices  of  steel,  as  Indicated  by  the  composite  price  reported  by 
Iron  Age,  have  shown  considerable  flexibility  since  1926. 

There  has  been  even  more  fluctuation  in  the  mill  net  yield,  i.  e.,  the  amount 
received  per  ton  by  the  U.  S. Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  on  the  various 
products  after  deduction  of  cost  of  delivery.  The  mill  net  yield  index 
declined  from  an  average  of  100  in  1926  to  a  low  of  73.5  in  1933.  The  in- 
creases in  prices  in  1 937  were  the  result  of  Increased  wag  js  and  other  costs. 
Factors  tending  to  lower  mill  net  yields  with  respect  to  reported  base 
prices  are  principally  (a)  reductions  from  base  price,  (b)  excess  of  actual 
cost  of  delivery  over  freight  added  to  base  price  in  computing  the  deliv- 
ered price,  (c)  quantity  discounts  and  (d)  deductions  for  quality,  size,  etc. 
Factors  tending  to  raise  mill  net  yield  with  respect  to  reported  base  prices 
are  principally  (a)  extras  for  special  finish,  quality,  size,  heat  treatment, 
etc.,  and  (b)  extras  for  small  quantity. 


13812 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Reported  composite  price  and  composite  mill  net  yield 
[1926=1001 


Com- 

MUl 

Net 
Yield 

Com- 
posite 
Price 

Mill 
Net 
Yield 

Com-       Mill 
posite       Net 
Price      Yield 

1912 

Jan 

1916 

Jan 

1920 

Jan    

61.6 
60.5 
60.2 
61.9 
62.9 
63.5 
65.0 
67.1 
69.5 
71.7 
73.4 
74.5 

57.9 
57.3 
57.5 
57.6 
58.1 

68: 9 
59.6 
60.8 
60.9 
61.9 

89.0 
95.2 
105.7 
112.8 
118.8 
116.2 
114.0 
115.9 
119.4 
123.4 
130.5 
141.6 

67.3 
68.7 
7!  0 
74.2 
77.3 
79.2 
82.3 
84.0 
86.0 
88.2 
90.8 

152.7 
152.  7 
164.2 
170.9 
168.0 
166.3 
169.1 
172.7 
170.8 
162.5 
154.2 
133.1 

Feb 

Feb 

Feb 

122  2 

Mar 

Mar 

Mar 

122  3 

Apr 

Apr    . 

Apr 

123  5 

^y :~ 

May :     I":' 

May  . 

124  0 

Jun             -  - 

Jun . 

Jun    ... 

123.8 

Jul 

Jul  ...  . 

Sep 

Oct      

cfft:::::::::::: 

Oct 

Nov 

Nov 

Nov 

125  8 

Dec 

Dec 

Dec. 

126  5 

Jan 

Jan 

1913 

1917 

1921 

Jan 

76.6 
76.3 
77.1 
77.3 
74.6 
72.9 
72.0 
70.2 

67!  3 
65.0 
63.2 

63.3 
64.3 
65.2 
65.7 
66.0 
66.4 
66.2 
66.1 
6.5.9 
65.3 
64.2 
62.9 

146.2 
151.2 
161.5 
177.5 
197.1 
216.2 
230.4 
226.7 
218.1 
149.8 
148.8 
148.6 

98.8 
103.5 
107.3 
111.9 
115.4 
118.7 
123.3 
127.5 
131.5 
134.4 
134.2 
132.8 

129.1 
123.1 
115.9 
114.0 
114.5 
109.0 
102.2 
96.0 
93.0 
91.3 
88.8 
86.4 

126  1 

F^- 

Feb 

Feb " 

126  5 

Mm-" : 

Mar      

Mm-' "" 

126  6 

May':::::::: 

May  

May":':":"":" 

Jul- 

Jul 

Aug 

Jul 

106.1 

Aug.. 

Sep 

Aug 

98  7 

Sep 

Sep 

94  6 

Oct " 

Oct 

Oct 

90.4 

Nov 

Nov          .    . 

Nov 

Dec        

Dec 

Dec 

Jan        

Jan 

Feb. 

Mar 

1914 

1918 

1922 

Jan.. 

62.7 
63.8 
63.6 
62.6 
61.5 
60.4 
60.5 
62.5 
63.5 
62.5 
60.3 
59.0 

61.2 
60.8 
61.2 
61.1 
60.5 
59.9 
59.0 
59.2 
59.4 
59.6 
59.5 

153.3 
153.3 
153.3 
153.3 
153.3 
153.3 
153.3 
153.3 
153.3 
153.3 
153.3 
149.5 

139.3 
137. 6 
136.1 
135.8 
137.9 
138.2 
139.4 
139.5 
140.6 
142.1 
142.6 
140.2 

84.6 
82.2 
82.2 
85.1 
87.7 
90.1 
91.5 
87.0 
101.6 
103.6 
103.3 
102.4 

K.I 

Feb.. 

Feb... 

Mar 

Mar 

82  8 

Apr 

Anr 

Apr 

82  7 

May" 

May 

May 

82  9 

Jun 

Jun 

Jun 

Jul 

Jill 

Jul    . 

84.2 

AUB 

Sep 

86.2 

Oct 

Oct  . 

Oct 

87.3 

Nov 

Nov 

Nov 

88.6 

Dec 

Dec 

Dec 

90.0 

Jan 

Jan 

1916 

1919 

1923 

Jan 

59.7 
60.3 
61.0 
62.1 
61.9 
62.4 
63.5 
65.3 
67.3 
70.6 
76.4 
83.8 

58.2 
58.0 
58.1 
58.8 
59.1 
59.6 
60.1 
60.4 
61.0 
62.1 
63.1 
64.5 

145.6 
145.6 
141.8 
130.9 
130.5 
130.5 
130.5 
130.5 
129.8 
131.8 
133.2 
134.3 

136.1 
134.7 
132.1 
125.4 
123.9 
122.0 
121.9 
121.  5 
121.2 
121.5 
120.8 
121.6 

103.7 
109.5 
115.5 
119.9 
119.7 
118.6 
118.6 

us:  6 
118.6 
lis.  6 
118.0 

91.9 

Feb 

Feb 

Feb    . 

Mar 

Mar    

Mar          

96.0 

Apr 

triy 

Apr 

98  4 

mi 

Alay 

Jun 

100.4 

Jun     

Jun 

101.9 

Jul... 

Jul 

Jul 

Aug 

Sep 

Sep 

106.2 

Oct 

Oct 

Oct 

107  7 

Nov 

Nov 

Nov 

110.4 

Deo 

Dec  .. 

Dec 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13813 

Reported  composite  price  and  composite  mill  net  yield — Continued 
[1926=100] 


Com- 
posite 
Price 


Mill 
Net 
Yield 


118.6 
117.5 
115.0 
112.0 
100.2 
108.0 
105.8 
103.6 
101.8 
101.0 
101.6 
103.6 


112.6 
112.7 
113.0 
112.6 
111.0 
108.3 
107.3 
105.3 
104.2 
102.0 
101.4 
101.2 


104.1 
104.6 
104.7 
102.0 
100.6 
99.6 
99.5 
98.7 
97.7 
98.3 
99.8 
100.6 


101.9 
102.3 
102.9 
103.0 
102.3 
100.7 
100.2 
100.3 
99.7 
99.7 
99.5 
99.6 


100.3 

99 

100.0 

100 

100.3 

99 

10(1. 1 

10(1 

99.5 

100 

99.7 

99 

100.0 

99 

100.0 

99 

100.0 

99 

100.0 

99 

100.0 

99 

100.0 

99 

98.5 
95.9 
96.5 
96.2 
95.7 
95.5 
95.4 
95.4 
95.0 
93.0 
92.1 
92.1 


98.7 
98.0 
97.0 
96.6 
95.9 
96.4 
96.3 
96.3 
95.9 
94.9 
95.2 
93.5 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr- 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr- 
May 
Jun. 
Jul-. 
Aug- 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr- 
May 
Jun." 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec- 


Feb. 
Mar- 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep., 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Com- 
posite 
Price 


MUl 
Net 
Yield 


92.3 
93.7 
94.1 
94.0 

92!  6 


94^2 
94.5 


92.9 
92.4 
92.7 
92.9 
93.9 


94.7 
94.7 
94.7 
96.0 
96.2 
96.6 
96.2 
95.6 
95.4 
94.9 
94.7 
95.2 


94.2 
94.2 
93.9 
94.3 
94.2 
94.3 
95.0 
95.4 
94.5 
94.3 
94.3 
94.0 


93.4 
92.8 
92.7 
90.6 
88.8 

87^2 
86.3 
85.9 
85.6 
85.4 
84.8 


92.4 
91.6 
91.2 
89.9 

86.6 
86.0 
85.0 


85.4 

82.2 

85.6 

83.2 

85.6 

82.3 

85.3 

81.8 

85.3 

81.4 

84.8 

80.4 

84.4 

79.9 

84.0 

79.8 

84.0 

81.9 

84.0 

80.0 

83.8 

81.3 

82.5 

80.2 

Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct., 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr- 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug- 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Com-  Mill 
poslte  Net 
Price      Yield 


81.4 

80.9 

80.6 

78.5 

77.8 

78.fi 

81.1 

81.3 

81.6 

84.2 

83.5 

84.0 

13814 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Reported  composite  price  and  composite  mill  net  yield — Continued 
[1926=100] 


Com- 
posite 
Price 

Mill 
Net 
Yield 

Com- 

Mill 
Net 
Yield 

Com- 
posite 
Price 

Mill 
Net 
Yield 

1936 

Mar.    -     -- 

1937 

May 

Jun..  

Jul 

Aug 

Sep 

1938 

Jan 

89.1 
88.1 
87.3 
87.6 
87.6 
87.8 
90.3 
90.3 
90.5 
91.4 
91.4 
95.0 

89.0 
89.1 
87.6 
86.4 
87.1 
88.2 
87.3 
88.1 

9o!o 

90.6 

106.2 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 
108.5 

93.3 
95.8 
98.0 
99.8 
101.6 
101.9 
103.4 
105.7 
104.8 
105.  3 

108.3 
106.2 
99.4 
99.4 
99.0 
97.4 
98.7 
98.7 

104.4 

Feb 

Apr 

102.7 

Mar 

May 

97.9 

Jul 

Oct 

93.7 

Sep 

Nov 

Dec 

Jan, 

Feb --. 

Mar 

M^ay:;::::;:;:: 

Jun 

Jul -. 

91.6 

An? 

Oct 

92  2 

Sep 

Nov _ 

Oct 

Dec 

1939 

Nov 

Jan 

Dec 

1938 

98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
97.5 
96.6 
96.6 

93.2 

1937 

108.  5         105. 4 

95.8 
95.1 

97.1 

91.4 
92.3 

108.5 
108.5 
108.5 

105.1 
105.9 
104.3 

94.8 

Jan 

Mar 

92.1 

91.4 

The  reported  compositp  price  index  is  based  upon  the  Iron  Age  composite  price  which  is  an  arithmetic 
average  of  the  reported  base  prices  of  eight  representative  finished  steel  products. 

The  composite  mill  net  yield  index  represents  the  amount  per  ton,  relative  to  that  for  1926,  received  by 
U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  (after  freight)  on  a  representative  constant  assortment  of  all  principal 
products. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13815 


's  ZD  "  "^  —  ■-  "^  s  ""  i 

-^'-'o-0    0>-C      •C-n?f->- 

-Oco^aO      oogg. 
.     .    «J    o    S    o  ?--2    S    o 

-D=oJ3-§  :£8£-t® 
I  E  fe  s  S.-^  »-^1  8.S 
^^  s:^ll  2^  S  i"^ 

®  .1  .If  ^  -o      E    «   I  ^   § 

it:?  o  -"S  S3-_£  E 
-c"e-S|  g-S.  i~-»  § 

1^ :-o ii  o.|S2f 

6 


lr|i  .1 


§S  I 


sag  R 

SU^SWnN    XBQNI 


13816 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Proportion  of  steel  cost  in  price  of  finished  product,  1938 — typical  products  of 
portant  steel  consuming  industries 


J'roduot 

Estimated 
Price 

EstlEnated 
Cost  of 
Steel 

Steel  Cost 

Remarks 

Reinforced      Concrete 
Road. 

Dairy  Barn 

$55,000 
$2,600 

$218 

$4,000 

$938,000 
11.8«S 
$730 

$112 

$33,400 
$2,260 

$400 
$83 

$7 

$172 

$55,077 

1.22* 

$77 

$25 

pi  2, 300 

$898 

0.7 
3.2 

3.4 

4.3 

6.9 
10. 4 
10.5 

22.3 

36.8 
39.9 

One  mUe  of  twenty  foot  concrete  highway 
in  Indiana.  Steel  cost  is  cost  of  16,000 
pounds  of  reinforcing  bars. 

Roof  sizes  30'  x  60'.    Steel  cost  Is  cost  of 

Electric  Refrigerator. . . 

galvanized  sheets  for  roof  only,  and  ex- 
cludes other  items  such  as  nails,  staples, 

Six  ou.  ft.  capacity  refrigerator.    Steel  cost 
is  cost  of  200  pounds  of  steel,  principally 
sheets,  and  excludes  steel  in  motor  and 
refrigerating  unit. 

Apartment  BuUding... 
Can  of  Food  Products- 

cost  is  cost  of  8,000  pounds  of  radiators, 
boiler,  water  tahk,  pipe,  metal  lath,  nails, 
gutters,  conduit,  etc. 

SU  story  flre-proof,  walk-up  apartment 
house  in  N.  Y.  Steel  cost  Is  cost  of  fabri- 
cated but  unerected  structural  steel. 

Average  price  of  cans  of  tomatoes,  peas  and 
com  In  N.  Y.  Steel  cost  Is  cost  of  tin 
plate. 

Typical  low-priced  four  door  sedan  de- 
livered In  N.  Y.  Steel  cost  is  cost  of 
2,800  pounds  of  sheets,  strip,  pig  iron, 
bars,  etc. 

Average  ef  fifteen  low-priced  farm  imple- 
ments. Steel  cost  estimate  is  based  on 
average  weight,  and  steel  cost  of  $60  per 
ton. 

One  mUe  of  new  track,  including  ballast, 
ties,  rails  and  fastenings.  Steel  cost  is 
cost  of  raUs  and  fastenings. 

Typical  60  ton  capacity  hopper  car.    Steel 

Farm  Implement- 

Railroad  Track-. 

Freight  Car 

cost  Is  cost  of  38,000  pounds  of  plates, 
shapes,  wheels,  axles,  etc. 

Above  data  are  necessarUy  estimates  but  are  believed  to  reflect,  with  reasonable  accuracy,  the  propor- 
tion of  steel  cost  In  the  price  of  the  finished  product. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13817 


PROPORTION  OF  STEEL  COST  IN  PRICE  OF  FINISHED  PRODUCT 
OTHER  COSTS  INCL  PROFIT  I  1  STEEL  COST 


REINF.  CONCR.  ROAD 
DAIRY  BARN 
ELEC.  REFRIGERATOR 
FRAME  HOUSE 
APARTMENT  BID'G 
CAN  OF  FOOD  PROD'S 
AUTOMOBILE 
FARM  IMPLEMENT 
RAILROAD  TRACK 
FREIGHT  CAR 


PRICE  OF  FINISHED  PRODUCT  =  100% 
20%  40%  60% 


A  10%  REDUCTION  IN  THE  PRICE  OF  STEEL  CAN  HAVE  BUT  RELATIVELY  LIHLE 
EFFECT  ON  THE  PRICE  OF  MOST  FINISHED  PRODUCTS 


The  cost  of  steel  is  a  relatively  smjjl  part  of  the  price  of  most  finished 
products.  For  example,  th"fe.csst  of  the  steel  in  a  low-priced  automobile 
averages  about  10%  of  the  delivered  price  to  the  ultimate  consumer 
Consequently,  a  10%  reduction  in  the  cost  of  steel,  if  entirely  passed 
on  to  the  consumer,  would  reduce  the  price  only  I  %. 


13818       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Automobile  steel  consumption  and  steel  prices  in  United  States 


Year 

.Automo- 
bile Steel 

Con- 
sumption 
(Tlious. 
Or.  Tons) 

Automo- 
bile Steel 
Price 
(Cents 

per 
Pound) 

Compos- 
ite Steel 
Price 
(Cents 

per 
Pound) 

Year 

Automo- 
bile Steel 

Con- 
sumption 
(Thous. 
Or.  Tons) 

Automo- 
bile Steel 
Price 
(Cents 

per 
Pound) 

Compos- 
ite Steel 
Price 
(Cents 

per 
Pound) 

1923  . 

4,182 
2,981 
4.886 
5,486 
4,895 
6,963 
6,545 
4,406 

3.73 
3.45 
3.04 
2.99 

2:67 
2.69 
2.44 

2.697 
2.505 
2.334 
2.315 
2.202 
2.165 
2.209 
2.048 

1931 

1932 

1933    - 

3,149 

1,864 
3,530 
4,101 
6,016 
6,712 
6,077 
3,619 

2.18 
1.98 
1.89 
2.22 
2.22 
2.^ 
2.73 
2.60 

1  957 

1924 

1925 

1.901 
1.879 

1926 

1934 

1927.. 

1928 

1936 

1929 

1937 

1930 

1938 

2  394 

Source:  Automobile  steel  consumption  data  are  based  on  figures  of  Iron  Age.  Steel  price  figures  are  from 
Iron  Age,  automobile  steel  price  data  representing  average  of  prices  of  hot  rolled  strip  and  hot  and  cold  rolled 
sheets. 


AUTOMOBILE  STEEL  CONSUMPTION  AND  STEEL  PRICES 

IN  UNITED  STATES 

9 
8 
7 
6 

CO 

1  ' 

4 

u. 
O 

<o       3 

z 
o 

=!       2 

s 

1 

9 

8 

7 

6 

5       g 

4       2 

K 

3       ^ 

<A 

2       £ 
o 

1 

^TOMQB 

LESl 

EEL 

^ 

^ 

^ 

v. 

\ 

UNbU 

/ 

\ 

/ 

N 

s 

/ 

\ 

\ 

^^ 

AU 

TOMO 

3ILE 

\ 

i 

y 

^ 

=^ 

*==:! 

=== 

EtLHKICL 

=5= 

^ 

^ 

... 



:^ 

STEE 

.PRI 

E 

r 

^illilllsllilllll^ 

Automobile  steel  consumption  and  steel  prices  have  little,  If  any,  relation 
to  each  other.  Hence,  factors  other  than  steel  prices  must  govern  auto- 
mobile steel  consumption. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13819 

Automobile  steel  consumption  and  automobile  production  in  United  States 


Year 

Automobile 
Steel  Con- 
sumption 
(Thous. 
Or.  Tons) 

Automobile 

Production 

(Thous. 

Cars) 

Year 

Automobile 
Steel  Con- 
sumption 
(Thous. 
Or.  Tons) 

Automobile 

Production 

(Thous. 

Cars) 

1923.   ..      . 

4,182 
2,981 

51486 
4,895 
6,963 
6,545 
4,406 

4,180 
3,738 
4,428 
4,506 
3,580 
4,601 
5,622 
3,510 

1931 

3,149 
1,864 
3,530 
4,101 
6,016 
6,712 
6,977 
3,619 

2.4?2 
1,431 
1  986 

1924 

1932 

1925 

1933 

1926 

1934 

2,870 
4  120 

1927 

1935 

1928 

1936 

4,616 
5,016 
2,655 

1929 _... 

1930 

1938 

Source:  Automobile  steel  consumption  data  are  based  on  figures  of  Iron  Age.    Automobile  production 
data  are  from  Statistical  Abstract  of  the  United  States,  and  Automobile  Manufacturing  Association. 


AUTOMOBILE  STEEL  CONSUMPTION  AND  AUTOMOBILE  PRODUCTION 

IN  UNITED  STATES 

,       z 

5        o 

-1 
i 

7 
6 

CO 

§       5 

:i    4 

3 
2 

1 
0 

JTOMC 

>OII  t 

ETC  CI 

/ 

<, 

CONSUMPTION 
(GMSS  TONS) 

/ 

"^ 

y 

s 

/ 

/ 

/ 

J 

\ 

/' 

^ 

V. 

/ 

x 

y 

\ 

1 

\ 

/ 

N 

J 

y'] 

/ 

\ 

K 

/ 

/. 

N 

'^ 

PW 

»ua 

(CARS) 

OH 

. 

s  1  1  i  i  i 

§|gS||||g||2 

Production  of  automobile  steel  is  closely  associated  with  and  dependent 
upon  production  of  automobiles.  Accordingly,  the  dsmand  for  automobile 
steel  is  determined  by  factors  which  govern  the  demand  for  automobiles, 
rather  than  by  factors,  such  as  price  of  automobile  steel,  within  the  control 
~f  *Ua  <teel  industry. 


124401— 41-rpt.  2(j- 


13820       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  Basing  Point  Method  of  Quoting  Delivered  Prices  in  the  Steel 
Industry 

The  basing  point  practice  in  the  steerindustry  is  a  simple  method  of  quoting 
delivered  prices,  which  results  in  the  competition  of  many  geographically  sepa- 
rated steel  producers  at  the  markets  for  each  of  the  diversified  products  of  modern 
steel  mills.  It  is  not  a  price-fixing  medium  nor  does  it  result  in  high  prices.  It 
does  not  stifle  price  competition  but  rather  extends  the  benefits  of  such  competition 
to  all  consumers. 

This  basing  point  practice  has  evolved  over  a  period  of  more  than  half  a  century 
to  meet  fundamental  economic  conditions  in  the  steel  industry.  Delivered  prices 
result  from  the  buyer's  need  to  know  the  cost  to  him  of  steel  delivered  at  his  plant, 
since  transportation  charges  from  mill  to  consumer  are  often  a  substantial  part  of 
the  value  at  the  place  of  consumption. 

The  producer  of  steel  must  take  into  consideration  all  of  the  elements  of  cost 
involved,  from  the  transportation  of  raw  materials,  through  the  processes  of  con- 
verting such  raw  materials  into  steel  products,  to  the  final  delivery  of  such  prod- 
ucts to  the  consumer.  It  requires  more  than  four  tons  of  raw  materials  to  produce 
one  ton  of  finished  steel.  The  location  of  facilities  for  producing  pig  iron  and  steel 
ingots  must  be  determined  largely  by  the  factor  of  raw  material  assembly  costs. 
This  Hmits  the  location  of  blast  furnaces  and  open  hearth  furnaces  to  a  few  areas 
where  the  raw  materials  are  readily  available.  In  turn,  the  economies  of  integra- 
tion cause  the  location  of  rolling  mills  near  the  steel  producing  units.  Large  well- 
integrated  mills,  designed  to  supply  the  scattered  markets  of  the  entire  country, 
have  been  constructed  in  such  areas.  These  mills  produce  many  diversified  prod- 
ucts in  order  to  utilize  ingot  capacity  to  the  fullest  extent  and  achieve  low  produc- 
tion cost  per  unit.  A  modern  integrated  mill  must  serve  more  than  its  immediate 
area;  it  must  reac'h  many  of  the  important  markets  for  its  diversified  products  in 
order  to  obtain  an  even  flow  of  orders.  Thus,  concentration  of  production  facili- 
ties in  a  few  areas  and  wide  distribution  of  products  is  a  rule  in  the  steel  industry 
enforced  by  economic  considerations.  The  result  is  competition  at  all  consuming 
points  between  several  geographically  separated  producers. 

.The  demand  for  steel  is  subject  to  enormous  fluctuations  in  the  business  cycle. 
The  capacity  of  the  industry,  including  reserve  capacity,  is  not  more  than  sufl5cient 
to  supply  the  needs  of  the  country  during  periods  of  high  demand,  such  as  1929, 
1937  and  the  present  time.  Less  capacity  would  result  in  scarcity  and  high  prices 
during  such  periods.  The  problem  of  adjustment  to  the  fluctuations  of  the  busi- 
ness cycle  is  solved  in  the  most  economical  way.  While  the  industry  is  constantly 
constructing  new  facilities  to  incorporate  technological  advances,  the  older  mills 
which,  although  outmoded,  have  not  served  their  full  useful  life,  are  retained  in 
reserve  to  meet  the  demand  at  high  levels  of  consumption. 

Most  criticisms  of  the  basing  point  method  disregard  entirely  these  fundamental 
economic  facts.  The  steel  industry  is  often  judged  by  criteria  derived  from  ab- 
stract theory,  based  upon  imaginary  conditions  which  cannot  exist.  Natural  de- 
viations from  these  criteria  are  arbitrarily  assumed  to  be  evils  and  are,  without 
demonstration,  ascribed  to  the  basing  point  method.  Critics  sometimes  rest  their 
case  solely  upon  bland  assertions  and  rhetorical  exaggeration.  In  many  instances, 
mere  name-calling  is  resorted  to.  Thus,  in  the  language  of  some  critics,  the  prac- 
tice of  meeting  competitive  prices  at  a  distance  becomes  "freight  absorption'  ;  the 
resulting  difference  in  mill  net  returns  becomes  "price  discrimination";  the  result- 
ing shipments  from  other  than  the  mill  nearest  the  destination  becomes  "cross- 
hauling";  and  .the  realization  of  a  competitive  advantage  due  to  superior  geo- 
graphical locat'uin  becomes  "phantom  freight." 

Competitive  forces  determine  the  pirices  quoted  at  all  destinations.  To  obtain 
Dusiness  in  a  market  at  a  distance  froih  his  mill,  a  producer  must  meet  competitive 
prices  quoted  by  other  producers  nearer  to  such  markets;  he  must  pay  the  freight 
necessary  to  transport  the  steel  product  to  the  consumer;  and  he  will  therefore 
realize  a  lower  mill  net  return  than  on  sales  to  consumers  nearer  his  mill.  This 
enables  him  to  operate  his  mill  at  a  lower  unit  cost  and  thus  to  sell  to  the  nearby 
consumer  for  less  than  he  otherwise  could. 

There  will  always  be  some  shipments  of  similar  products  past  each  other  in 
opposite  directions  unless  competition  between  geographically  separated  pro- 
ducert,  is  arbitrarily  limited  to  the  marginal  territory  between  their  mills.  Even 
under  the  uniform  f.  o.,  b.  mill  price  system  proposed  by  the  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission, shipments  would  not  always  be  made  from  the  nearest  mill.  The  alleged 
economic  waste  resulting  from  cross-shipments  must  be  balanced  against  the 
countervailing  advantages  to  the  public  of  a  competitive  system,  and  also  against 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13821 

the  economic  losses  which  would  follow  from  artificial  limitation  of  marketing 
territories. 

If  an  isolated  producer  is  located  nearer  than  other  producers  to  an  important 
market,  he  wiU  be  able  to  realize  a  higher  miU  net  return.  In  so  doing,  he  may 
be  merely  taking  proper  advantage  of  his  superior  geographical  location,  or  he 
may  need  such  higher  return  to  compensate  for  his  additional  costs  in  assembling 
and  processing  raw  materials.  He  can  obtain  higher  mill  net  returns  than  some 
of  his  competitors  either  by  announcing  a  higher  price  at  his  mill,  or  by  merely 
meeting  the  competitive  delivered  prices  of  other  producers.  .  Characterizing  tht 
latter  practice  as  the  collection  of  freight  charges  which  are  not  paid  is  a  distortion 
of  the  facts. 

Transportation  of  steel  products  by  water  vehicles  and  trucks  has  received 
attention  unwarranted  by  its  true  importance,  and  significant  factors  in  the 
situation  have  been  overlooked.  The  practical  availability  of  each  of  these 
mediums  of  transportktion  is  circumscribed  by  many  inherent  limitations. 
The  producer  located  so  as  to  be  able  to  transport  some  products  by  water  has 
an  advantage  over  other  producers  not  so  located,  which  he  is  properly  entitled 
to  realize  by  a  higher  mill  net  return.  His  advantage  often  lies  merely  in  the 
ability  to  reach  markets  from  which  rail  freight  rates  would  bar  him.  Where  all 
the  circumstances  warrant  it,  the  advantage  is  passed  on  to  consumers  by  lower 
delivered  prices.  The  producer's  advantage,  however,  is  one  which  may  easily 
turn  into  a  disadvantage.  If  be  gives  one  consumer  the  benefit  of  the  saving 
resulting  from  water  transportation,  he  may  soon  have  to  make  the  same  price  to 
aE  consumers  in  the  area  and  ship  by  rail,  with  freight  disadvantages  which  will 
lower  his  rpill  net  returns.  Shipment  by  truck  seldom  involves  an  appreciable 
freight  saving,  and  often  involves  additional  freight  cost.  The  added  expense 
and  inconvenience  to  the  producer  in  truck  shipments  justify  any  additional 
charges'  made. 

The  proposed  alternative  to  the  basing  point  method  is  a  uniform  f.  o.  b.  rnill 
price  system.  The  effects  of  this  system  would  be  extremely  complex,  and  are 
therefore  largely  unforeseeable.  Its  exponents  propose  it  in  the  name  of  abstract 
theory,  and  have  outlined  its  characteristics  and  effects  only  with  respect  to  the 
elimination  of  supposed  evils  of  the  basing  .point  method.  They  have  never 
described  the  operation  of  the  system  nor  analyzed  its  effects  in  relation-  to  the 
economic  facts  of  the  steel  industry. 

The  uniform  f.  o.  b.  mill  price  system  is  expected  by  its  exponents  to  eliminate 
high  cost,  inefficient  and  supposedly  uneconomically  located  miUs  and  to  break 
up  concentration  of  production  facilities,  by  forcing  the  erection  of  small  mills 
in  all  parts  of  the  country.  Such  results,  even  if  they  wo\iId  be  accomplished  by 
the  system,  would  conflict  with  basic  economic  factors,  and  necessarily  increase 
present  production  and  transportation  costs. 

The  system  is  also  expected..to  increase  existing  competitton.  This  is  to  be 
accomplished  by  the  extraordinary  means  of  arbitrarily  limiting  the  competition 
between  miUs  not  adjacent  to  each  other  to  marginal  territory.  Each  mill,  or 
group  of  mills,  would  be  restricted  in  distribution  to  a  circumscribed  area  subject 
to  only  slight  possible  variations  in  size.  Each  c'ustomer  would  be  confined  to  a 
single  or  a  very  few  sources  of  supply.  The  capacities  of  mills  would  be  limited 
to  the  consumption  in  the  prescribed  territories,  and  any  existing  additional 
capacity  would  have  to  be  scrapped.  Serious  dislocations  in  the  steel  industry 
and  in  industries  dependent  upon  it  would  be  inevitable. 

'Under  a  uniform  f.  o.  b.  mill  price  system,  local  monopolies  and  high  assembly 
and  production  costs  would  displace  the  present  widespread  competition  and  low 
costs.  I 

The  following  diagrams,  prepared  by  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  are, 
designed  to  clarify  the  operation  of  the  basing  point  method  of  quoting  delivered 
prices  in  the  steel  industry  by  means  of  a  few  simple  illustrations  of  typical 
basic  situations.  While  a  good  deal  of  mystery  seems  to  have  been  made  of 
the  basing  point  practice,  it  is  actually  simple  and  easily  understandable.  These 
diagrams  do  not  purport  to  give  a  complete  picture  of  the  price  competition  which 
exists  in  the  sale  of  steel  products.  In  particular,  it  must  not  be  concluded  that 
the  prices  of  steel  products  at  any  consuming  point  are  inflexibly  determined  by 
the  application  of  the  basing  point  practice — competition  between  different 
steel  producers  is  keen  .and  often  results  in  delivered  prices  at  the  consuming 
point  considerably  lower  than  the  delivered  prices  which  would  reuslt  from  the 
application  of  the  basing  point  method  as  illustrated  by  these  diagrams. 

October  30,  1939. 


13822 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


THE  BASING  POINT  METHOD 
Most  steel  products  are  sold  on  a  Delivered  Price  basis. 

Diagram  1 :  How  the  Delivered  Price  is  computed. 


& 


■0 


DELIVERED  PRICE 


Base  price  is  used  herein  In  the  sense  of  the  announced  price  at  the  basing 
point,  wltnout  freight  or  extras,  and  delivered  price  is  used  herein  in  the 
sense  of  the  price  at  the  consuming  point,  not  including  extras. 

If  the  base  price  at  a  basing  point  is  $40  per  ton  and  freight  therefrom 
to  a  consuming  point  Is  $4  per  ton.  the  delivered  price  at  such  consuming 
point  is  $44  per  ton. 


Note:    The  bqse  price  o(  $40,  used  In  this  and  subsequent  diagrams,  is  purely  arbitrary 
and  is  not  to  be  talen  as  an  actual  price.  Prices  vary  for  different  steel  products. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13823 


THE  BASING  POINT  METHOD 
Diagram  2:  Explanation  of  Freight  Disadvantage  and  Freight  Absorption. 

Mill  at  (A)  has  lowest  Base  Price  plus  Freight  to  jx]. 
Mills  at  (B)  and  ©  are  at  a  Freight  Disadvantage; 
to  sell  at  [x]  they  must  absorb  Freight. 


BASING  /-TN  BASE  PRICE    $40 

POINT   \^  FRT  OISADV       2 

T   MILL  NET         38 


G> 


BASE  PRICE  $40 
FR-T  OISADV  0 
MILL  NET         40 


'con; 

4f- 


•<5) 


BASE  PRICE  $40 
FITT  OISADV.  3 
MILL  NET         37 


A,  B  and  C  are  basing  points,  at  each  of  which  a  base  price  of  $40  per  ton 
is  announced  by  the  mills  located  there.  X  Is  a  consuming  point.  If  the 
freight  rate  from  each  basing  point  to  X  were  added  to  the  base  price 
at  each  basing  point  three  delivered  prices  would  result,  $43.  $45  and 
$46  per  ton,  the  delivered  price  from  A  being  the  lowest.  However,  a 
consumer  at  X  naturally  will  not  pay  more  than  $43  per  ton,  the  lowest 
delivered  price  quoted.  Consequently,  competition  forces  the  mills  at 
B  and  C  also  to  quote  a  delivered  price  of  $43  per  ton  at  X,  which  re- 
sults In  their  mill  net  returns  being  reduced  to  $37  and  $38  per  ton,  re- 
spectively, whic^  amounts  are  below  their  base  prices. 

Since  such  reduction  below  the  base  price  is  necessitated  by  the  freight 
disadvantage  of  the  mills  at  B  and  C.  it  Is  often  called  "freight  absorp- 
tion" by  the  critics  of  the  basing  point  practice.  The  inference  Is  that 
such  mills  are  paying  a  higher  freight  rate  than  they  charge  to  the 
customer.  In  reality,  they  are  not  charging  any  amount  for  freight,  but 
are  quoting  such  a  delivered  price  as  Is  necessary  to  meet  the  comfjetltlon 
of  the  more  favorably  located  mill  at  A,  and  paying  the  freight  necessary 
to  make  dellverv  at  the  consuming  point 


13824 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


THE  BASING  POINT  METHOD 
Diagram  3:  Explanation  of  first  type  of  Freight  Advantage  and  so-called  "Phantom  Freight" 

Mill  at  (A)  has  lowest  Base  Price  plus  Freight  to  [x]. 

Mill  at  ©  charges  the  same  Delivered  Price.  Having  a  Freight 
Advantage  of  $  1  ^)ver  (A),  ©  realizes  a  Mill  Net 
$  1  higher  than  (A).  This  $  1  is  so-called  "Phantom  Freight". 


NON-BASING 
POINT 

NO  BASE  PRICE  © 
fRT  ADV.       $1 
MILL  NET       41 


& 


CONSUMINr 
I 1     POINT 

►[x> 


A  and  B  are  basing  points,  at  each  of  which  a  base  price  of  $40  per  ton  is 
announced  by  the  mills  located  there,  c  is  not  a  basing  point  because 
the  mill  at  c  sees  fit  not  to  announce  bf>se  prices  at  c,  but  merely  meets 
the  competitive  delivered  prices  of  othJrjriHs.  The  mill  at  c  at  any  time 
In  its  discretion  may  decide  to  make  c  a  basing  point.  At  consuming 
point  X,  the  lowest  delivered  price  from  a  basing  point  mil!  is  $44  per 
ton,  computed  upon  $40  base  price  plus  $4  freight  from  A.  If  the  mill  at 
B  sells  at  X,  it  is  at  a  freight  disadvantage  of  $  I  per  ton  and,  accordingly, 
its  mill  net  return  will  be  $1  per  ton  less  than  its  base  price. 

The  non-basing  point  mill  at  c,  however,  has  a  freight  advantage  of  $  I  per 
ton  over  the  mill  at  A  in  selling  at  X.  By  meeting  the  competitive  delivered 
price  of  A  at  X,  the  mill  at  c  receives  a  mill  net  return  of  $41,  or  $1  more 
than  the  mill  at  A  which  may  explain  why  it  has  not  decided  to  become 
a  basing  point.  This  amount  has  been  characterized  by  critics  of  the 
basing  point  practice  as  "phantom  freight",  the  inference  being  that  the 
mill  at  c  charges  the  customer  a  higher  freight  rate  than  it  pays.  In  reality, 
the  mill  at  c  merely  names  a  delivered  price  at  X  which  permits  it  to 
realize  the  benefit  of  its  freight  advantage  due  to  superior  geographical 
location.  It  would  realize  this  same  advantage  if  it  announced  a  base 
price  at  c  of  $41  per  ton. 

Smce  there  are  today  very  few  non-basing  point  mills,  very  little  freight 
advantage  of  this  type  is  now  realized  in  the  steel  industry. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13825 


THE  BASING  POINT  METHOD 
Diagram  4:  Explanation  of  second  type  of  Freight  Advantage  and  so-called  "Phantom  Freight" 
Mill  at  (D  has  lowest  Base  Price  plus  Rail  Freight  to  [x] 
Mill  at  (a)  charges  the  same  Delivered  Price. 
When  mill  at  (A)  ships  by  water  it  has  a  Freight  Advantage 
of  $1  and  realizes  a  Mill  Net  $1  above  its  Base  Price. 
This  $1  is  so-called  "Phantom  Freight". 


BASE  PRICE  $40'^^============================^DEL1VEREO  BASE  PRICE 

FRT  ADV.  (WATER)       1  FREIGHT  (WATER)  $2  price  $43  MILL  NET 

MILL  NET  $41 


Note:  When  mill  at  (a)  ships  by  rail  it  is  at  a  Freight  Disadvantage 
of  $1  and  realizes  a  Mill  Net  $1  below  its  Base  Price. 


A  and  B  are  basing  points,  at  each  of  which  a  base  price  of  $40  per  ton 
is  announced  by  the  mills  located  there.  X  is  a  consuming  point,  at  vvhich 
the  lowest  delivered  price,  using  rail  freight  rates,  Is  $43  per  ton.  If  the 
mill  at  A  sells  at  X,  and  ships  by  rail,  It  Is  at  a  freight  disadvantage  of  $1 
per  ton.  If  it  meets  the  delivered  price  of  B  at  X  and  ships  by  rail,  it  will 
realize  $  I  per  ton  less  than  Its  base  price. 

If  the  mill  at  A  ships  by  water  to  X,  It  has  a  freight  advantage  of  $1  per 
ton.  If  it  meets  the  delivered  price  of  B  at  X  and  ships  by  water,  the  mill 
at  A  realizes  the  benefrt,of  Its  water  freight  advantage  and  obtains  a 
mill  net  return  $1  per  tor  higher  than  Its  base  price.  This  advantage,  when 
thus  realized,  Is  also  characterized  by  critics  of  the  basing  point  method 
as  "phantom  freight". 

In  reality,  steel  mllfs  realize  very  little  freight  advantage  or  "phantom 
freight"  of  this  type. 


13826 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


THE  BASING  POINT  METHOD 
Diagrams:  Determination  of. Boundary  between  Natural  Market  Territories 
The  Boundary  dividing  the  Natural  Market  Territories  of  mills  at 
Basing  Points  (t)  and  (B)  is  the  line  0-0  connecting  the 
points  at  which  the  Delivered  Prices  from  (A)  and  (§)  are  equal. 


j^*^'   DEUVEREO 


7 


CONSUMING     X-a^ 


/C-^ 


\y> 


BASING  /  <'  DEUVEREO 
POINT  /^^^  PRICE  J45 
(X^-l iRilGHJJS _^  - 

BASE  PRICE 
$40 

0 

BOUNDARY 


E»45| 

""^T-'CON 


FREIGHT  $5 


.---® 


A  and  B  are  basing  points,  at  each  of  which  a  base  price  of  $40  per  ton  is 
announced  by  the  mills  located  there.  X.  Y  and  Z  are  consuming  points, 
each  of  which  is  equi-distant  freightwise  from  A  and  B.  The  line  0-0  con- 
necting these  points  is  the  boundary  between  the  natural  market  territories 
of  the  mills  at  A  and  B.  As  thus  defined,  natural  market  territory  refers  to 
the  area  in  which  a  mill  can  sell  at  the  competitive  delivered  price  without 
realizing  less  than  its  base  price.  In  sales  at  X,  Y  and  Z  and  at  points  on  its 
side  of  the  line  0-0,  either  the  mill  at  A  or  the  mill  at  B  realizes  a  mill  net 
return  equal  to  its  base  price. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  lOCONOMIC  FOWEll  13827 


THE  BASING  POINT  METHOD 
Diagram  6:  How  shipping  beyond  Boundary  of  Natural  Market  Territory  reduces  Mill  Net. 

When  mill  at  (§)  sells  to  [x],  its  Mill  Net  is  $40. 

When  mill  at  (§)  sells  to  [y],  its  Mill  Net  is  only  $37  because: 

1.  Freight  is  $2  higher. 

2.  Delivered  Price  is  $1  lower. 


I- 
»•* 

/I 
pSNT(J).___JiE!GHIiL__J2'!lV[x}*- i''l'£.fi2.~~rir^ 


DELIVERED 

PRICE  $41  _ 

/I 
BASING    - 


BASING 
•~...        POINT 


BASE  PRICE    $40 

MILL  NET  (XorY) 

$40 


BASE  PRICE  $40 
MILL  NET  (X)  40 
MILL  NET  lY)  37 


0 

BOUNDARY 


A  and  B  are  basing  points,  at  each  of  which  a  base  price  of  $40  per  ton  Is 
announced  by  the  mills  located  there.  At  consuming  point  X,  located  on 
the  boundary  0-0  between  the  natural  market  territories  of  the  mills  at  A 
and  B.  the  delivered  price  Is  $42  per  ton,  calculated  with  reference  to  the 
freight  rate  from  either  basing  point.  At  consuming  point  Y,  the  delivered 
price  is  $41  per  ton.  equivalent  to  the  base  price  at  A  of  $40  per  ton,  plus 
$  I  freight  from  A  to  Y. 

When  the  mill  at  B  sells  at  X,  Its  mill  net  return  equals  its  base  price,  but 
when  It  sells  at  Y,  its  mill  net  return  is  reduced  by  the  effect  of  two  factors. 
First,  the  delivered  price  Is  $  I  per  ton  less  than  at  X.  Second,  the  freight 
rate  from  B  to  Y  is  $4  per  ton,  or  $2  more  than  from  B  to  X.  Thus,  the  mill 
net  return  of  ttie  mill  at  B  Is  reduced  $3  per  ton  below  its  base  price. 
It  may  be  advisable  for  the  mill  at  B  to  sell  at  Y  and  realize  a  mill  net 
return  $3  per  ton  below  its  base  price  In  order  to  obtain  a  higher  operat- 
ing rate  and  thus  secure  a  lower  average  unit  production  cost. 


13828 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


THE  BASING  POINT  METHOD 

Diagram?:  Non-basing  Point  Mill. 

Mills  at  Basing  Points  (a)  and  (f)  realize  full  Base  Pnces  on  sales  in  their 

respective  Natural  Market  Territories. 

Non-basing  Point  mill  at  ©  has  no  Base  Price  and  meets  the  Delivered  Prices 

of  (A)  and  (§)  when  it  sells  in  their  respective  Natural  Market  Territories. 

( 

NON- 
BASING 
POINT 

MILL 

© 

) 

BASING 
POINT 

© 

BASE  PRICE 
$40 

BASING 
POINT 

® 

BASE  PRICE 
$40 

0 

BOUNDARY 

A  and  B  are  basing  points,  at  each  of  which  a  base  price  of  $40  per  ton  is 
announced  by  the  nnilis  located  there,  c  is  not  a  basing  point,  because 
the  mill  at  c  sees  fit  not  to  announce  base  prices  at  c,  but  merely  meets 
the  competitive  delivered  prices  of  other  mills.  The  line  0-0  is  the  boundary 
of  the  natural  market  territories  of  the  mills  at  A  and  B.  Since  the  mill  at 
c  announces  no  base  price  at  c,  with  which  its  mill  net  retums  may  be 
compared,  it  has  no  natural  market  territory  in  the  sense  in  which  that  term 
Is  used  in  these  diagrams.  Either  the  mill  at  A  or  the  mill  at  B  can  sell  at 
points  nearer  c  than  A  or  B,  respectively,  without  reducing  its  mill  net 
return  below  its  base  price,  as  long  as  the  mill  at  c  follows  its  practice  of 
meeting  competitive  delivered  prices  of  other  mills. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13829 


THE  BASING  POINT  METHOD 
Diagram  8:  Effect  of  naming  new  Basing  Point 
After  (C)  becomes  a  Basing  Point  the  Boundary  00  between  (A)  and  (f) 

ceases  to  be  significant 
Mill  at  (C)  then  has  a  Natural  Market  Territory,  bounded  by  NN  and  N'N',  in 

which  it  establishes  lower  Delivered  Prices  than  (A)  or  (|) 
To  sell  in  this  territory,  mills  at  Basing  Points  (A)  and  (B)  must  now  absorb  freight 


© 

BASE  PRICE 
»40 


BOUNDARY  BOUNDARY  BOUNDARY 


When  the  mill  at  C  decides  to  announce  a  base  price  at  C  and  C  thus 
beconnes  a  basing  point,  the  line  N-N  beconnes  the  boundary  between 
the  natural  market  territories  of  the  mills  at  A  and  C  and  the  line  N'-N' 
becomes  the  boundary  between  jhe  natural  market  territories  of  the  mills 
at  B  and  C.  The  line  0-0,  which  marked  the  former  boundary  between  the 
natural  market  territories  of  the  mills  at  A  and  B,  now  ceases  to  be  signifi- 
cant, because  the  mill  net  returns  of  the  mills  at  A  and  B  are  reduced  on 
sales  to  any  point  between  N-N  and  N'-N',  respectively,  regardless  of 
whether  or  not  such  point  is  beyond  the  line  0-0.  The  natural  market  terri- 
tory of  the  mill  at  C  has  been  carved  out  of  the  former  natural  market 
territories  of  the  mills 'at  A  and  B. 


13830 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


THE  BASING  POINT  METHOD 
Diagram  9:  Illustration  of  Cross-hauling. 

Products  shipped  from  (A)  to  [Y]  go  past  products  shipped  from  (§)  to  [Y| 
This  involves  Cross-hauling  only  if: 

1.  The  products  shipped  are  identical. 

2.  Shipments  occur  at  substantially  the  same  time 


CONSUMING 
POINT 

FREIGHT  $6 

BASING 
POINT 
/CN  BASE  PRICE 

BASING  rK^ 

,/' 

POINT   \^ 

BASE  PRICE 
$40 

FREIGHT  J6 

CONSUMING 
POINT 

A  and  B  are  basing  points,  at  each  of  which  a  base  price  of  $40  per  ton  is 
announced  by  the  mills  located  there.  X  and  Y  are  consuming  points,  at 
each  of  which  the  lowest  delivered  price  calculated  with  reference  to  the 
nearest  basing  point,  is  $42  per  ton.  When  the  mill  at  A  sells  at  Y  or  when 
the  mill  at  B  sells  at  X,  In  either  case  meeting  the  competitive  delivered 
price  at  the  consuming  point,  the  mill  net  return  Is  reduced  $4  per  ton 
below  the  base  price.  When  the  mill  at  A  ships  to  Y  and  the  mill  at  B  ships 
to  X.  the  shipments  cross  each  other,  in  a  broad  sense,  and  this  is  said 
by  critics  of  the  basing  point  practice  to  constitute  "cross-hauling".  This 
is  a  very  controversial  term.  Under  a  proper  interpretation  of  the  word, 
there  is  no  cross-hauling  unless  the  products  shipped  fro/n  A  to  Y  and  from 
B  to  X  are  Identical  and  unless  the  shipments  occur  at  substantially  the 
sanoe  time.  "Cross  hauling"  Is  the  necessary  result  of  competition  In  the 
steel  industry. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13831 


THE  BASING  POINT  METHOD 

Diagram  10:  Effect  of  Basing  Point  price  differential  (Supplementary  to  Diagram  3). 
In  selling  at  [x]  or  any  point  up  to  the  Boundary  0-0  of  its  Market  Territory,  mill  at  (§) 

realizes  its  higher  Base  Price  and  freight  added  equals  freight  paid. 
In  selling  at  |Y|,  mill  at  (C)  realizes  less  than  its  Base  Price,  although: 

1.  It  realizes  more  than  mill  at  (A). 

2.  Freight  added  exceeds  freight  paid.  o 


BASE  PRICE  $40 


BASE  PRICE  $45 


0 

BOUNDARY 


A  Is  a  basir>g  point,  at  which  a  base  price  of  $40  per  ton  is  announced  by  the  mill  located  there.  C  is  a 
new  basing  point  at  which  a  base  price  of  $45  per  ton  has  recently  been  announced  by  the  nnill  located 
there.  X  and  Y  are  consuming  points  at  which  oelivered  prices  of  i46.50  and  $46  per  ton,  respectively, 
are  quoted. 

Before  C  became  a  basing  point,  the  mill  at  C  merely  met  the  delivered  price  of  $46.50  quoted  at  X 
by  the  basing  point  mill  at  A,  and  realized  a  mill  net  return  of  $45  per  ton,  which  was  $5  more  than  that 
of  the  mill  at  A.  This  amount  is  characterized  by  critics  of  the  basing  point  method  as  "phantom  freight." 
When  C  becomes  a  basing  point,  with  the  announcement  of  a  base  price  of  $45  per  ton  by  the  mill 
at  C,  the  price  at  X  is  unchanged,  since  the  combination  of  base  price  at  C  plus  freight  from  C  to  X 
equals  the  delivered  price  computed  with  reference  to  A.  The  mill  at  C  still  realizes  a  mill  net  return  of 
$45  per  ton,  which  is  $5  higher  than  that  of  the  mill  at  A.  This"  amount  can  no  longer  be  characterized 
as  "phantom  freight." 

Lllcewlse,  before  C  became  a  basing  point,  the  mill  at  C  merely  met  the  delivered  price  of  $46  Quoted 
at  Y  by  the  mill  at  A,  and  received  a  mill  net  return  of  $44  per  ton,  which  was  $4  more  than  that  of 
the  mill  at  A.  When  C  becomes  a  basing  point,  with  a  base  price  of  $45  per  ton,  the  lowest  delivered 
price  at  Y  is  still  the  base  price  at  A  plus  freight  from  A  to  Y.  The  mill  at  C  still  receives  a  mill  net  return 
of  $44  per  ton.  or  $4  more  than  that  of  the  mill  at  A.  Although  the  mill  net  return  of  the  mill  at  C  is  now 
$  I  lower  than  Its  base  price.  It  may  still  be  charged  with  collecting  "phantom  freight,"  since  the  freight 
paid  (C  to  Y)  is  less  than  the  freight  used  (A  to  Y)  in  computing  the  delivered  price  at  Y. 
Actually,  the  higher  mill  net  returns  realized  by  the  mill  at  C,  both  before  and  after  C  is  named  a  bas- 
ing point,  represent  the  proper  realization  by  the  mill  at  C  of  Its  superior  geographical  location  with 
respect  to  sales  at  X  and  Y.  The  mill  at  C  may  need  such  higher  returns  to  meet  higher  raw  material 
assembly  or  production  costs. 


13832 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


THE  BASING  POINT  METHOD 
Diagram  11:  Freight  Disadvantage  reduced  by  Water  Shipment  (Supplementary  to  Diagram  4). 

Mill  at  (a)  has  $2.50  Freight  Disadvantage  when  shipping  to  [x] 

by  rail,  and  Mill  Net, js  reduced  $2.50 
Mill  at  (A)  has  only  $.75  Freight  Disadvantage  when  shipping  to  [x] 

by  water,  and  Mill  Net  is  reduced  only  $.75 


DELIVERED  PRICE  $42 


BASE  PRICE  $40 


A  and  B  are  basing  points,  at  each  of  which  a  base  pn.e  of  $40  per  ton 
is  announced  by  the  mills  located  there.  X  is  a  consuming  point  at  which 
the  lowest  delivered  price  is  $42  per  ton,  calculated  witti  reference  to  the 
freight  rate  from  B.  If  the  mill  at  A  sells  at  X,  and  ships  by  rail,  it  is  at  a 
freight  disadvantage  of  $2.50  per  ton,  and  realizes  $2.50  per  ton  less  than 
its  base  price.  If  the  mill  at  A  ships  by  water  to  X,  it  is  still  at  a  freight 
disadvantage  of  $.75  per  ton  and  realizes  $.75  per  ton  less  than  its  base 
price. 

The  advantage  of  the  water  shipment  merely  reduces  the  freight  disadvan- 
tage of  the  mill  at  A  from  $2.50  per  ton  on  rail  shipments  to  $.75  per  ton, 
when  shipped  by  water. 


-^ 


MARKET   TERRITORIES  OF  MAJOR   MILLS 
PRODUCING    STEEL    SHEETS 

Assuming  Each  Such  Mill  Adopts  A  Uniform  P.O.  B.  Mill 
'^rice  Equal  To  Prevailing  Base  Prices 


LACKAWANNA 
PITTSBURGH 


6-  VANOERGRIFT 
WEIRTON,  BEECH  80TT0« 

6.  STEUBENVILLE 
YOUNSSTOWN,  CAMPBELL 

6.  M'  DONALD 
WARREN 
CLEVELAND 
CANTON. MASSILLON. 
PORTSMOUTH 
ASHLAND 
MIDDLETOWN 
GRANITE  CITY 
CHICAGO 

GARY,  INDIANA  HARBOR 
MONROE 
DETROIT 


124491 — »0— pt.  28      (Face  p. 


LEGEND 

A      APOLLO 

BB    BEECHBOTTOM 

Br     BRACKENRID6E 

Bu    BUTLER 

Ci    CANTON 

CI     CLEVELAND 

0      ORAVOSBURG 

L      LACKAWANNA 

M     MASSILLON 

N      MILES 

P      PITTSBURGH 

SP    SPARROWS  POINT 

S      STEUBENVILLE 

V  VANDERSRIFT 
W.  WARREN 
We  WEIRTON 

Y  YOUNGSTOWN 

o-  McDonald 


DETAILED  A\AP  OF  COUNTIES 
IN  WESTERN  PENNSYLVANIA  AND  EASTERN  OHIO 

Showing  towns  controlled  by  mills  producing  steel  sheets 
each  such  mill  adopts  a  uniform  F.O.6.  mill  price 
equal    to    prevailing    base    price. 


VHVi\ — 40— pt.  2B      (Face  p.  13833)      No.  2 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13833 


Some  Effects  of  Proiposed  Uniform-  F.  O.  B.  Mill  Price  System 

A  uniform  f.  o.  b.  mill  price  system  would  require  each  mill  to  name  a  price  at 
the  mill  applicable  to  aU  sales.  The  combination  of  mill  price  and  transporta- 
tion charges  from  mill  to  destination  would  determine  the  delivered  cost  of  steel 
to  the  consumer.  Generally,  the  delivered  cost  at  any  destination  would  vary 
as  between  different  producing  mills,  and  the  consumer  naturally  would  buy 
from  the  mill  offering  the  lowest  delivered  cost,  i.  e.,  the  mill  having  the  lowest 
combination  of  mill  price  and  freight  from  mill  to  the  particular  destination.  A 
mill  could  sell  only  in  the  area  in  which  the  combination  of  its  mill  price  and 
freight  from  mill  to  destination  would  be  the  lowest. 

MAP  NO.   1 MARKET  TERRITORIES   OF  MAJOR  MILLS  PRODUCING  STEEL  SHEETS 

Map  No.  1  illustrates  some  immediate  consequences  of  the  introduction  of  the 
proposed  system.  Seventeen  major  sheet  producing  points  are  shown,  with  sell- 
ing territories  to  which  mills  at  such  points  would  be  restricted  in  the  sale  of 
sheets  under  the  proposed  system,  assuming  present  freight  rates  and  mill  prices 
equal  to  present  base  prices  at  nearest  basing  points.  (This  results  in  equal  mill 
prices  at  all  mills,  except  at  Detroit  and  Granite  City,  where  the  mill  price  is  $2 
higher,  and  at  Monroe,  where  the  mill  price  is  $3  higher.)  On  this  map,  terri- 
tories are  determined  by  counties  according  to  freight  rates  to  one  or  two  key 
towns,  and  mills  adjacent  to  each  other  are  considered  as  a  single  producing 
point. 

Local  monopolies  are  the  rule;  competitive  areas  the  exception.  AU  important 
sheet  markets  are  in  the  monopoly  area  of  a  single  producing  point,  or  a  produc- 
ing point  group  such  as  Chicago-Gary.  Sheet  consumption  is  slight  in  areas  of 
competition. 

Size  of  monopoly  areas  depends  generally  upon  the  proximity  of  other  m^ills. 
Sparrows  Point  and  Lackawanna  together  have  monopolies  of  all  North  Atlantic 
seaboard  markets.  Chicago-Gary  has  a  monopoly  of  Wisconsin,  Northern  Il- 
linois, Iiforthern  Indiana,  and  Western  Michigan.  In  contrast.  Western  Penn- 
sylvania and  Eastern  Ohio  mills,  having  large  capacities,  are  restricted  to  small 
areas. 

Territorial  allocation  is  extremely  arbitrary.  Warren  and  Youngstown  mills, 
for  example,  each  have  monopolies  in  their  home  counties;  they  share  territories 
to  the  north  of  Warren,  but  Warren,  passing  Youngstown,  reaches  territory 
south  of  Youngstown,  which  Youngstown  cannot  reach.  Chicago-Gary  mills 
share  most  territory  which  either  can  reach,  including  the  home  county  of  each ; 
but  Chicago,  passing  Gary,  has  a  monopoly  in  certain  Indiana  counties;  and 
Gary,  after  passing  exclusive  Chicago  territory,  has  a  monopoly  in  many  other 
Indiana  counties. 

Note.— This  map  necessarily  pictures  the  situation  at  a  single  relative  price  level.  Differences  in  rela- 
tive price  levels  would  change  market  territories  of  mills,  but  would  not  eliminate  the  pattern  of  local 
monopoly  and  fixed  territories  here  shown. 

A  mill  in  close  proximity  to  other  mills  would  tend  to  swallow  up  their  entire  market  areas  in  seeking  to 
widen  its  own  market  area  by  lowering  its  mill  price. 

At  any  relative  level  of  their  prices,  two  mills  could  generally  compete  in  only  one  important  market, 
since  automatically  the  price  of  the  first  would  exclude  the  second,  or  the  price  of  the  second  would  exclude 
the  first,  from  every  other  such  market. 

MAP  NO.  2 DETAILED  MAP  OF  COUNTIES  IN  WESTERN  PENNSYLVANIA  AND  EASTERN 

OHIO 

Map  No.  2_shows  miscroscopically  a  section  of  the  area  sliown  on  Map  No.  1, 
and  further  illustrates  in  detail  some  immediate  consequences  of  the  introduction 
of  a  uniform  f.  o.  b.  mill  price  systern.  On  Map  No.  1,  selling  territories  are 
determined  by  county.  On  Map  No. '2,  each  town  is  separately  marked  with 
the  symbol  of  the  mill  or  mills  which  could  sell  in  such  towns  under  the  proposed 
system,  assuming  mill  prices  equal  to  present  base  prices  at  nearest  basing  points, 
and  present  freight  rates.  The  closer  scrutiny  thus  afforded  indicates  that  the 
problem  is  more  complex  than  Map  No.  1  shows. 

Local  monopolies  are  even  more  striking  on  Map  No.  2.  In  many  areas  shown 
on  Map  No.  1  as  enjoying  competition  from  more  than  one  producing  point,  there 
are  actually  only  a  few  towns  where  competition  occurs.  Many  towns  are  ac- 
cessible to  only  one  mill.  For  example,  Columbiana  County,  Ohio,  is  shown  on 
Map  No.  1  as  an  area  of  competition  between  Warren  mills  (including  Niles) 
and  Weirton-Beechbottom-SteubenviUe  mills.  Actually,  as  shown  on  Map  No. 
2,  three  towns  are  accessible  to  Niles  only,  one  town  to  Steubenville  only^  and 


13834  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

one  town  to  Canton  only.  Similarly,  Westmoreland  County,  Pennsylvania,  is 
shown  on  Map  No.  1  as  an  area  of  competition  between  the  Pittsburgh  group  of 
mills  and  the  Butler-Vandergrift-Apollo  mills.  Actually,  as  Map  No.  2  indicates, 
the  Dravosburg  mill  has  a  monopoly  in  six  towns,  and  the  Vandergrift  mill  in 
another,  while  Dravosburg  and  Apollo  compete  in  one  town,  and  Pittsburgh, 
Brackenridge,  and  Vandergrift  compete  in  another. 

Mills  located  close  to  each  other  are  shown  as  groups  on  Map  No.  1,  and  thus 
competition  between  them  throughout  the  group  territory  is  indicated  on  such 
map.  The  separate  detailed  consideration  of  each  mill  and  each  town  on  Map 
No.  2  shows  local  monopolies  and  arbitrary  restrictions  of  selling  points  even  in 
such  territories.  For  example,  Cambria  County,  Pennsylvania,  is  in  the  joint 
territory  of  Butler-Vandergrift-Apollo  on  Map  No.  1.  Actually,  as  shown  on 
Map  No.  2,  Apollo  has  a  monopoly  in  five  towns,  while  Apollo  and  Vandergrift 
compete  in  three  others.  In  Weirton-Beechbottom-Steubenville  territory: 
Beechbottom  has  a  monopoly  of  all  towns  in  Belmont  County,  Ohio;  in  Jeffer- 
son County,  Ohio,  Steubenville  a  monopoly  in  two  towns,  and  Canton  in  another, 
while  Steubenville  and  Weirton  compete  in  one  town. 

Note.— While  this  map  is  necessarily  based  on  a  single  relative  level  of  prices  at  different  mills,  it  is  not 
believed  that  the  pattern  shown  on  the  map  would  greatly  change  at  any  pdssible  relative  level.  Prices 
at  adjacent  mills  would  be  identical,  since  each  would  be  oblieed  to  meet  another's  price  reductions  im- 
mediately, or  lose  its  entire  selling  territory. 

Composite  mill  net  yield  and  cost  per  weighted  ton  shipped,  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 

and  subsidiaries 

[1926=100] 


Year 

Composite  Mill  Net  Yield 

Year 

Jan. 

Feb. 

Mar. 

Apr. 

^ay 

June 

July 

Aug. 

Sept. 

Oct. 

Nov. 

Dec. 

1926.... 

99.8 

100.0 

99.6 

100.2 

100.1 

99.8 

99.8 

99.5 

99.9 

99.6 

99.9 

99.8 

1926 

1927.... 

98  7 

98.0 

97.0 

96.6 

95.9 

96.4 

96.3 

96.3 

95.9 

94.9 

95.2 

93.  5 

1927 

1?28._.- 

93.4 

93.4 

93.3 

93.4 

94.3 

93.8 

92.9 

92.4 

92.7 

92.9 

93.9 

93.7 

1928 

1929.... 

94.2 

94.2 

93.9 

94.3 

94.2 

94.3 

95.0 

95.4 

94.5 

94.3 

94.3 

94.0 

1929 

1930.... 

92.4 

91.6 

91.2 

89.9 

88.9 

88.0 

86.6 

86.0 

85.0 

83.7 

83.3 

82.0 

1930 

1931.-.. 

82.2 

83.2 

82.3 

81.8 

81.4 

80.4 

79.9 

79.8 

81.9 

80.0 

81.3 

80.2 

1931 

1932  ... 

78.6 

79.1 

79.3 

78.7 

77.7 

79.2 

79.5 

79.3 

79.0 

78.8 

78.2 

77.9 

1932 

1933... 

77.0 

76.0 

76.6 

75.0 

74.5 

74.6 

73.  5  • 

75.0 

77.2 

79.4 

82.6 

83.5 

1933 

1934  ... 

87.1 

88  1 

87.4 

87.1 

88  5 

87.4 

91.8 

92.9 

91.9 

93.3 

92.5 

89.9 

1934 

1935  ... 

92.1 

92.0 

91.9 

91.9 

92.0 

91.2 

90.5 

90.8 

90.0 

89.6 

88.8 

89.6 

1935 

1936.... 

89.0 

89.1 

87.6 

86.4 

87.1 

88.2 

87.3 

88.1 

88.8 

89.6 

90.0 

90.6 

1936 

1937  ... 

91.4 

92.3 

95.8 

98.0 

99.8 

101.6 

101.9 

103.4 

105.7 

104.8 

105.8 

m7 

1938  ... 

105.4 

105.1 

105.9 

104.3 

104.4 

102.7 

97.9 

96.2 

95.9 

93.7 

91.6 

92.2 

i9;w 

1939.... 

93.2 

94.1 

95.8 

95.1 

94.8 

92.1 

91.4 

91.4 

91.4 

92.2 

93.0 

The  composite  mill  net  yield  index  represents  the  amount,  relative  to  that  for  1926,  received  per  ton  by 
II.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  (after  freight)  from  sales  of  a  representative  constant  assortment  of  all 
principal  products. 


Cost  per  Weighted 
Ton  Shipped 

Year 

Cost  per  Weighted 
Ton  Shipped 

Year 

Actual 
Cost 

Estimated 
Cost  at 

1926 
Volume 

Actual 
Cost 

Estimated 
Cost  at 

1926 
Volume 

1926 

100.0 
103.6 
98.3 
91.8 
96.9 
105.6 
129.6 

100.0 
101.1 
97.2 
92,0 
92.8 
92.2 
91.7 

1933 

1934 

105.8 
115.0 
112.7 
105.9 
108.7 
124.  5 

85.1 

92.0 

1935 

96.6 

1936 

99.6 

1937.. 

106.3 

1938 

107.6 

1932                               

Actual  cost  per  weighted  ton  shipped  is  total  cost,  exclusive  of  bond  interest.  Federal  income  taxes,  mis- 
cellaneous non-operating  income  and  expense,  and  of  inter-company  items,  for  all  subsidiaries  of  U.  S.  Steel 
Coriioration,  divided  by  the  number  of  weighted  tons  shipped.  Weighted  tonnages  are  actual  tonnages, 
adjusted  for  change  in  proportions  of  high  and  low  cost  products  and  for  the  equivalent  tonnage  of  average 
cost  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  represented  by  products  other  than  steel.  The  cost  of  operations 
not  related  to  the  production  of  steel  is  included  in  total  cost,  but  since  such  cost  is  a  small  percentage  of 
the  total  and  since  the  other  operations  tend  to  expand  and  contract  with  the  volume  of  steel  production, 
the  relative  change  in  the  total  cost  per  weighted  ton  many  be  considered  fairly  indicative  of  the  change  in 
tlie  cost  of  producing  steel. 

Estimated  cost  if  1920  volume  maintained  is  the  actual  cost  per  weighted  ton  shipped  adjusted  to  1920 
volume  on  the  assumption  the.t  the  percentage  change  in  the  average  cost  per  ton  as  the  rseult  of  a  given 
change  in  volume  would  have  been  the  .same  in  each  of  the  re^spective  years  as  it  is  estiraateii  to  have  been 
under  1938  conditions. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13835 


COMPOSITE  MILL  NET  YIELD  AND  COST  PER  WEIGHTED  TON  SHIPPED 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
1926  =  100 


A 

/ 

/ 

,      AC 

UALC 

OST 

/ 

V 

^-v- 

Y? 

K 

Q 

■<^ 

x^ 

,__ 

ESTI^ 
AT  -t 

ATEO  COST 
evOLUM^^ 

^ 

I 

\ 

^ 

r 

^ft» 

Yp 

"OSITE 
TYIEL 

V^ 

1 

^v^ 

^y 

IILLB 

D 

1926  1927  1928  1929  1930  1931  1932  1933  1934  1935  1936  1937  1938  1939  1940 


150 
140 
130 
120    ^ 

110    S 

s 

100  i 

90     2 
a 

z 
80      - 

70 

60 

50 


The  composite  milt  net  yield  index,  which  is  indicofive  of  the  level  of  steel 
prices,  hos  generally  been  lower  thon  the  index  of  octuol  costs  per  ton 
since  1926.  This  is  true  even  if  the  effect  on  costs  of  chonges  in  the  Operoting 
rate  is  eliminated,  as  shown  by  the  index  of  the  estimoted  costs  per  ton  if 
1926  volume  hod  obtained  throughout  the  period.  In  the  base  year  1926, 
with  the  various  subsidiaries  operoting  ot  on  overoge  rote  of  89%,  U.  S. 
Stjel  Corporation  realized  6.2%  on  its  investment. 


124491— 41— pt.  26 


13836 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Relation  of  mill  net  yield  to  reported  base  price,  U.  S.  Steel .  Corporation  Subsidies, 
February  1939 


Cents  per  Pound 

Item 

H'y  Struc- 
tural 
Shapes 
(at  Pitts- 
burgh) 

H'y  Struc- 
tural 
Shapes 

(at 
Chicago) 

Plates  (at 
Pitts- 
burgh) 

Cold 
Rolled 
Sheets 

2.100 
.145 

2.100 
.099 

2.100 
.154 

3,200 

Extras 

.041 

Total - - - -- - 

2.245 

2.199 

2.254 

3.241 

Mill  Net  Yield  (Incl  Extras)                           -      ... 

2.062 
.122 

2.106 
.035 

2.061 
.119 

2.908 

Freight  Absorption ..-- - -- 

.145 

Total                                           -  -         -  .  - 

2.184 
.      .061 

2.141 
.058 

2.180 
.074 

3.053 

Price  Reductions 

.188 

Reported  Base  Price                                     - 

2.100 
2.062 

2.100 
2.106 

2.100 
2.061 

3.200 

Mill  Net  Yield  (Incl  Extras)                       

2.908 

.038 

•.006 

.039 

.292 

•Mill  net  yield  is  in  excess  of  reported  base  price. 

Reported  base  prices  are  as  reported  by  Iron  Age. 

Other  data  are  frf^m  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries'  reports  to  T.  N.  E.  C.  in  answer  to  Questionnaire 
Form  B,  entitled  "Distribution  and  Pricing  of  Selected  Steel  Products." 

Data  on  heavy  structural  shapes  and  plates  at  Pittsburgh  and  Chicago  are  for  shipments  from  Homestead 
and  South  Chicago  plants,  respectively.  Data  on  cold  rolled  sheets  are  for  shipments  from  Irvin  and  Gary 
plants. 

Freight  absorption  is  adjusted  for  basing  point  price  differentials. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13837 


QNnOd    a3d    SiN30 

oi 

o             in             o             in             o                                             1 

oc  s 

.              c.              ^              ^              in              o              1 

Q.  9 

P 

%% 

LlJ  § 

ili 

a 

£ 

IJ 

!■ 

pm 

% 

2a 

1 

5 

ii 

1 

rdco 

Q              ' 

2=i 

QNnOd    a3d    SiN30 

QNnOd    aSd    SiN30 

1;        CJ        O 


aNODd    a3d    SiN30 


11 


If 

8  J 

If 

d  ° 
8  § 
5.1 


2  c 

II 
II 

II 

«5  -£ 


1  i  2| 

S    9 


i 

J 
s 

.9    S. 

3i 

I  - 

B  = 
1% 

§  i 


§1 


s  -si 


9-  ~ 

Is 


111 


-      5  ^ 


«       ^ 


It 

5i  §  i 

S    °  -i: 

sis 


13838       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Average  delivered  price  and  freight  absorption,  February  1939  shipments  of  selected 
steel  products — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries 


Dollars  per 
Net  Ton 


Per  Cent  of 

Delivered 

Price 


Db.ivered  Price  (Incl.  Extras).... 
Freight  Absorption  (Unadjusted) 
Freight  Absorption  (Adjusted)... 


65.00 
1.99 
1.33 


100.0 
3.6 
2.4 


Data  are  from  U.  8.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries'  reports  to  T.  N.  E.  C,  In  answer  to  Questionnaire 
Form  B,  entitled  "Distribution  and  Pricing  of  Selected  Steel  Products." 

Delivered  price  is  "Total  Invoiced  Delivered  Value,"  as  shown  on  Form  B. 

Unadjusted  freight  absorption  is  difference  between  "Actual  Freight  Paid  or  Allowed  on  Shipments 
from  Mill  to  Destination"  and  "Freight  Charges  Added  to  Base  Prices  to  Arrive  at  Invoiced  Value,"  as 
shown  on  Form  B. 

Adjusted  freight  absorption  (as  defined  in  Department  of  Justice  "Supplement  to  Form  B  Tables," 
discussion  of  Table  9)  is  such  unadjusted  freight  absorption  decreased  by  the  amounts  by  which  the  basing 
point  prices  applicable  on  certain  sales  were  greate-  than  the  base  prices  at  other  basing  points. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13839 


AVERAGE  DELIVERED  PRICE  &  FREIGHT  ABSORPTION 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  SUBSIDIARIES 
FEBRUARY  1939  SHIPMENTS  OF  SELECTED  STEEL  PRODUCTS 

DOLLARS  PER 
NET  TON 

60 

100.0% 


DELIVERED  FREIGHT  FREIGHT 

PRICE  ABSORPTION       ABSORPTION 

(UNADJUSTED)  (ADJUSTED) 


Source:  Antwei  to  T.  N.  E.  C  Queaionnait' 


The  unadjusted  freight  absorption  (i.e.,  the  difference  between  "freight 
added"  and  "freight  paid")  per  net  ton  on  the  domestic  shipments  of 
selected  steel  products  from  selected  mills  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  sub- 
sidiaries made  during  February  1939  averaged  $1.99  a  ton  or  3.6%  of 
the  average  delivered  price  of  $55  per  ton,  including  extras.  The  adjusted 
freight  absorption  (i.e.,  the  unadjusted  figure  minus  basing  point  price 
differentials)  averaged  $1.33  a  ton  or  2.4%  of  the  average  delivered  price. 


13840  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Average  delivered  price  and  freight  absorption,  February  1939  shipments  of  selected 
steel  products — selected  producing  companies 


Item 

Dollars  per 
Net  Ton 

Per  Cent  of 

DeUvered 

Price 

Delivered  Price  (Incl  Extras) 

56.06 
1.77 
1.16 

100.0 

Freight  Absorption  (Unadjusted) 

3  2 

Freight  Absorption  (Adjusted) 

2.1 

Data  are  from  Department  of  Justice  Summary  compiled  from  T.  N.  E.  C.  Questionnaire  Form  B, 
entitled  "Distribution  and  Pricing  of  Selected  Steel  Products." 

Delivered  price  is  "Total  Invoice  Delivered  Value"  as  shown  on  Form  B. 

Unadjusted  freight  absorption  is  difference  between  "Actual  Freight  Paid  or  Allowed  on  Shipments 
from  Mill  to  Destination"  and  "Freight  Charges  Added  to  Base  Prices  to  Arrive  at  Invoiced  Value,"  as 
shown  on  Form  B. 

Adjusted  freight  absorption  (as  defined  in  Department  of  Justice  "Supplement  to  Form  B  Tables," 
discussion  of  Table  9)  is  such  unadjusted  freight  absorption  decreased  by  the  amounts  by  which  the  basing 
point  prices  applicable  on  certain  sales  were  greater  than  the  base  prices  at  other  basing  points. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13841 


AVERAGE  DELIVERED  PRICE  &  FREIGHT  ABSORPTION 

SELECTED  PRODUCING  COMPANIES 
FEBRUARY  1939  SHIPMENTS  OF  SELECTED  STEEL  PRODUCTS 

DOLLARS  PER 
NET  TON 

60 


50 


40 


30 


20 


10 


3.2% 


2.156 


DELIVERED  FREIGHT  FREIGHT 

PRICE  ABSORPTION       ABSORPTION 

(UNADJUSTED)  (ADJUSTED) 


Source:  Department  of  Justice  Summary 

Compiled  from  T.  N.  E.  C  Questionnaire  Form  B. 


The  unadjusted  freight  absorption  (i.e.,  the  difference  between  "freight 
added"  and  "freight  paid")  per  net  ton  on  domestic  shipments  of  selected 
steel  products  from  selected  mills  of  selected  producing  companies  mode 
during  February  1939  averaged  $1.77  a  ton  or  3.2%  bf  the  average 
delivered  price  of  $55.06  per  ton,  including/ extras.  The  adjusted  freight 
absorption  (i.e.,  the  unadjusted  figure  minus  basing  point  price  difPerentiais) 
averaged  $1.16  or  2.1%  of  the  average  delivered  price. 


13842 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Breakdown  of  average  delivered  price,  February  19S9  shipments  of  selected  steel 
products — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries 


Item 

Dollars  per 
Net  Ton 

Per  Cent  of 

Delivered 

Price 

66.00 
6.71 

49.29 
3.72 
1.99 
0.66 
1.33 

100.0 

Freight  Paid 

10  4 

Mill  Net  Yield  (Includtng  Ertras) 

80  6 

Freight  Added 

6.8 

Freight  Absorption  (Unadjusted) 

3.6 

Basing  Point  Price  Dlflerentlals 

1.2 

Freight  Absorption  (Adjusted) 

2.4 

Data  are  from  U.  8.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries'  report  to  T.  N.  E.  C.  In  answer  to  Questionnaire 
Form  B,  entitled  "Distribution  and  Pricing  of  Selected  Steel  Products." 

Delivered  price  Is  "Total  Invoiced  Delivered  Value"  as  shown  on  Form  B. 

Freight  paid  is  the  "Actual  Freight  Paid  or  Allowed  on  Shipments  from  Mill  to  Destination,"  as  shown 
on  Form  B. 

Mill  net  yield  Is  delivered  price  less  freight  paid. 

Freight  added  is  "Freight  Charges  Added  to  Base  Prices  to  Arrive  at  Invoiced  Value,"  as  shown  on 
Form  B. 

Unadjusted  freight  absorption  Is  difference  between  such  freight  ijaid  and  such  freight  added. 

Basing  point  price  dlflerentlals  (ta  defined  In  Department  of  Justice  "Supplement  to  Form  B  Tables," 
discussion  of  Table  9)  are  amounts  by  which  basing  point  prices  applicable  on  certain  sales  were  greater 
than  the  base  prices  at  other  basing  points. 

Adjusted  freight  absorption  (as  defined  In  Department  of  Justice  "Supplement  to  Form  B  Tables," 
discussion  of  Table  9)  is  diSerence  between  freight  absorption  (unadjusted)  and  such  basing  point  price 
differentials. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13843 


BREAKDOWN  OF  AVERAGE  DELIVERED  PRICE 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  SUBSIDIARIES 
FEBRUARY  1939  SHIPMENTS  OF  SELECTED  STEEL  PRODUCTS 


DOLURS  PER 
NET  TON 
60 


50 


40- 


30 


"DELIVERED" 
PRICE 
$55.00 


20- 


10- 


FRT 
PAID 
$5.71 


MILL 

NET 

YIELD 

$4929 


msi 


PRICE 

/DIFFERENTIALS  $0.66    I    FRT  ABSORPTION 
/  FRT  ABSORPTION  f  (UNADJUSTED)  $  1.99 

►^(ADJUSTED)  $1.33 

FRT  ADDED  $3.72 


Source:   Answer  to  T.N.E.G.  Questionnaire  Form 


The  "Freight  Charges  Added  to  Base  Prices  to  Arrive  at  invoiced  Value", 
as  shov/n  on  Form  B,  on  domestic  shipments  of  selected  steel  products  from 
selected  mills  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  made  during 
February  1939,  amounted  to  6.8%  of  the  delivered  price,  while  the  "Actual 
Freight  Paid  or  Allowed  on  Shipments  From  Mill  to  Destination",  as  shown 
on  Form  B,  amounted  to  10.4%. 

The  unadjusted  freight  absorption  amounted  to  3.6%  of  the  delivered 
price,  and  the  adjusted  freight  absorption,  after  deduction  of  the  amount 
of  basing  point  price  differentials,  amounted  to  2.4%  of  the  delivered  price. 


13844 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Breakdown  of  average  delivered  price,   February  1939  shipments  of  selected  steel 
products — selected  producing  companies 


Item 

Dollars  per 
Net  Ton 

Per  Cent  of 

Delivered 

Price 

65.06 
4.77 

50.29 
3.00 
1.77 
.61 
1.16 

100.0 

Freight  Paid 

8  6 

Mill  Net  Yield  (Including  Extras) 

91.4 

Freight  Added 

5.4 

Freight  Absorption  (Unadjusted) 

3.2 

Basing  Point  Price  Differentials                                             .                          .  . 

1.  1 

Freight  Absorption  (Adjusted) 

2.  1 

Data  are  from  Department  of  Justice  Summary  compiled  (rom  T.  N.  E.  C.  Questionnaire  Form  B, 
entitled  "Distribution  and  Pricing  of  Selected  Steel  Products." 

Delivered  price  is  "Total  Invoiced  Delivered  Value"  as  shown  on  Form  B. 

Freight  paid  Is  the  "Actual  Freight  Paid  or  Allowed  on  Shipments  from  Mill  to  Destination,"  as  shown 
on  F6rm  B. 

Mill  net  yield  is  delivered  price  less  freight  paid. 

Freight  added  is  "Freight  Charges  Added  to  Base  Prices  to  Arrive  at  Invoiced  Value,"  as  shown  on 
Form  B. 

Unadjusted  freight  absorption  is  difference  between  such  freight  paid  and  such  freight  added. 

Basing  point  price  differentials  (as  defined  in  Department  of  Justice  "Supplement  to  Form  B  Tables," 
discussion  of  Table  9)  are  amounts  by  which  basing  point  prices  applicable  on  certain  sales  were  greater 
than  the  base  prices  at  other  basing  points. 

Adjusted  freight  absorption  (as  defined  in  Department  of  Justice  "Supplement  to  Form  B  Tables," 
discussion  of  Table  9)  is  difference  between  freight  absorption  (unadjusted)  and  such  basing  point  price 
differentials. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13845 


BREAKDOWN  OF  AVERAGE  DELIVERED  PRICE 

SELECTED   PRODUCING  COMPANIES 
FEBRUARY  1939  SHIPMENTS  OF  SELECTED  STEEL  PRODUCTS 


DOLLARS  PER 
NET  TON 
60 


50 


40 


30 DELIVERED" 

PRICE 
$55.06 


20 


10- 


FRT  ABSORPTION 
(UNADJUSTED)  $1.77 


FRT  ADDED  $3.00 


MILL 

NET 

YIELD 

$50.29 


Source:  Department  c^  Justici  Summary 
Complied  from  T.N.E.C    ' 


The  "Freight  Charges  Added  to  Base  Prices  to  Arrive  at  Invoiced  Value", 
OS  shown  on  Form  B,  on  domestic  shipments  of  selected  steel  products  from 
selected  mills  of  selected  producing  companies  made  during  February  1939, 
amounted  to  5.4%  of  the  delivered  price,  while  the  "Actual  Freight  Paid  or 
Allowed  on  Shipments  from  Mill  to  Destination",  as  shown  on  Form  B, 
amounted  to  8.6%. 

The  unadjusted  freight  absorption  amounted  to  3.2%  of  the  delivered 
price,  and  the  adjusted  freight  absorption,  after  deduction  of  the  amount  of 
basing  point  price  differentials,  amounted  to  2.1%  of  the  delivered  price. 


13846  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Explanation  of  unadjusted  and  adjusted  freight  absorption 


Item 

Dollars  per 
Net  Ton 

Item 

DoUarsper 

Net  Ton 

Freight  Paid 

17.60 
8.40 
9.20 

49.00 
42.00 

Basing  Point  Price  Diflerential 

Freight  Absorption  (Adjusted) 

Base  Price  at  Producing  Point 

Freight  Absorption  (Adjusted) 

Mill  Net  Yield 

7.00 

Freight  Absorption  (Unadjusted) 

Basing  Point  Price  (Houston) 

2.20 
42.00 

Basing  Point  Price  (Chicago) 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13847 


EXPUNATION  OF  UNADJUSTED  &  ADJUSTED 
FREIGHT  ABSORPTION 


Chicago 


Dallas 


DELIVERED 
PRICE -^ 
$57.40 


FREIGHT 
PAID 
$17.60 


BASING  POINT- 

PRICE 
DIFFERENTIALS 

$7 

FRT  ABSORP. 

M 

FREIGHT 
ADDED 
$8.40 

FREIGHT 
ABSORPTION 

(UNADJUSTED) 

$9.20 


Houston  0 


The  unadjusted  freight  absorption  is  the  difference  between  freight  paid, 
$17.60,  and  freight  added,  $8.40,  or  $9.20.  However,  since  the  base  price 
applicable  on  the  sale  includes  a  difPerential  over  the  base  price  at  the 
producing  mill,  the  unadjusted  freight  absorption  is  partially  ofFset  by  the 
amount  of  differential.  The  adjusted  freight  absorption  is  the  difference 
between  the  unadjusted  freight  absorption  of  $9.20  and  the  differential  of 
$7.00,  or  $2.20. 

The  mill  net  yield  is  reduced  below  the  base  price  only  by  the  amount  of 
the  adjusted  freight  absorption. 


13848 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Section  D — Capacity  and  Production 


Total  ingot  capacity— U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  and  other  steel  producing 
companies 


Capacity  in  Thousands  of 
Gross  Tons 

Capacit 

y  In  Thousands  of 

U.S. 

Orcrss  Tons 

U.S. 

Steel  in 
%of 

Year 

Steel  In 

Year 

%of 

U.S. 
Steel 

Other 
Compa- 
nies 

Total 
U.S. 

Total 

U.S. 

U.S. 
Steel 

Other 
Compa- 
nies 

Total 
U.S. 

Total 
U.S. 

1901 _.. 

"9,431 

1  12,032 

21,463 

43.9 

1920 

22,353 

33,284 

65, 637 

40.2 

1902 

'  10,033 

1  12, 667 

1  22,700 

44.2 

1921 

22.694 

34,683 

67, 377 

39.6 

1903 

1  11,211 

1  12, 689 

'23,900 

46.9 

1922 ,.. 

22.694 

35,723 

68,417 

36.8 

1904 

'  11,548 

I  13, 642 

26,190 

45.8 

1923 

22,802 

35,843 

58,645 

38.9 

1905 

'  12,882 

'  13,418 

'26,300 

49.0 

1924 

22,  816 

36,616 

59, 432 

38.4 

1906 .- 

I  13,445 

'  13, 955 

'27,400 

49.1 

1926 

23,125 

38,012 

61,  137 

37.8 

1907 

14,777 

1  13, 723 

'28,500 

51.8 

1926 

22,749 

35,064 

67,  813 

39.3 

1908 

15,590 

'  14,710 

'30,300 

61.6 

1927 

23,17:^ 

36,  855 

60,032 

38.6 

1909 

17,  157 

I  16,843 

'34,000 

50.6 

1928 

23,762 

37, 703 

61.  465 

1910 

17,845 

"  17,  355 

135,200 

60.7 

1929 

24,202 

39,582 

63,784 

37.9 

1911 

18,083 

1  17,917 

'36,000 

60.2 

1930 

26, 163 

40,003 

68,166 

38.6 

1912 

18, 822 

'  19, 178 

'38,000 

49.6 

1931 

26, 075 

42,905 

68,980 

37.8 

1913 

18,496 

'  20,504 

'39,000 

47.4 

1932 

27,841 

42,499 

70,  340 

39.6 

1914 

18, 998 

20,691 

39,689 

47.9 

1933 

27,342 

42,849 

70, 191 

39.0 

1915.. _ 

19,228 

22,066 

41.294 

46.6 

1934 

27,342 

>  42, 413 

'  69, 755 

39.2 

1916 

20,841 

24,947 

45,788 

45.6 

1935 

27,342 

42,704 

70,046 

39.0 

1917.. 

22,046 

27,568 

49, 614 

44.4 

1936 

26,657 

43, 133 

69,790 

38.  2 

1918 

22,207 

30, 334 

52,641 

42.3 

1937 

25, 772 

44,003 

69, 775 

36.9 

1919 

22, 340 

32, 143 

H483 

41.0 

1938 

25,790 

46,804. 

•   71,694 

36.0 

Source:  Corporation  records  and  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute.    Data  as  of  January  1st  each  year. 

'  Partly  estimated. 

»  Figures  for  1934  and  subsequent  years  i  jlude  only  that  portion  of  capacity  of  steel  for  castings  used  hy 
foundries  operated  by  companies  producii    steel  ingots. 

Tennessee  Coal,  Iron  and  Railroad  Coupany  data  included  in  Corporation  figures  beginning  with  Jan- 
uary 1,  1908. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13849 


TOTAL  INGOT  CAPACITY 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  SUBSIDIARIES  AND  OTHER  STEEL  PRODUCING  COMPANIES 


eg     Csi     CM 


50 

" 

^ 

1 

*" 

- 

rr 

"" 

- 

- 

25 

n 

>.  STEEL  CAPAC 
%  OF  TOTAl 

i 

i 

i 

\ 

I 

I 

c 

0 

I 

c 

5 

i 

a 

t 

0 

5 

0 
0 

0 

s 

I 

I 

I 

T 

I 

s 

3 

I 

s 

] 

^ 

\ 

s 

\ 

s 

I 

o 

2 

Sexjrze:  CofVOratxjn  tKorfh  ami  Amn  lioo  (f  S*eW  /ns(. 


Ingot  capacity  of  the  steel  industry  increased  steadily  until  1932  (the 
decrease  ^n  the  total  curve  in  1 926  was  due  to  a  readjustment  of  capacity 
data  by  the  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute,  rather  than  to  an'abandon- 
ment  of  facilities  to  produce  steel).  Since  1932  the  capacity  of  the  country 
has  remained  practically  unchanged,  as  a  result  of  the  reduced  demand  for 
steel,  particularly  from  the  railroad  and  construction  industries. 

U.  S.  Steel  Corporation's  portion  of  the  total  capacity  of  the  country  has 
decreased  from  a  high  of  52%  in  1 908  to  36%  in  1 938. 


13850 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Steel  ingot  capacity  compared  with  population — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries 
and  total  United  States 


Year 

Capacity— Thous. 
Gross  Tons 

Population 
Total  U.  8. 
(Thou- 
sands) 

Capacity  Per  Cap- 
ita—Pounds 

U.  8.  Steel 

Total  U.  S. 

U.8.8. 

U.S. 

1884 

2,821 

13,675 

4,529 

5,270 

16.866 

6,461 

16,803 

1  7, 145 

7,487 

18,607 

9,726 

110,864 

12,002 

113.086 

H169 

1  16. 635 

118,900 

21,463 

122,700 

123.900 

25.190 

126.300 

127.400 

128.600 

130.300 

134.000 

135.200 

136,000 

138,000 

139,000 

39,689 

41.294 

45,788 

49,614 

52,541 

54,483 

65,637 

67,377 

68,417 

68.645 

59. 432 

61, 137 

57,813 

60,032 

61, 465 

63, 784 

65,166 

68,980 

70, 340 

70. 191 

'  69. 755 

70. 046 

69.790 

69. 776 

71,594 

66,  379 
56,658 

59)  217 
60,496 
61, 775 
63.056 
64,361 
65.666 
66,970 
68.275 
69,580 

72!  189 
73,494 
74,799 
76,129 
77, 747 
79, 365 
80,983 
82,601 
84,219 
85,837 
87,455 
89,073 
90.691 
92, 267 
93, 682 
95, 097 
96,  512 
97,928 
99,343 
100,758 
102. 173 
103.688 
105.003 
106.543 
108,208 
109,873 
111,  537 
113, 202 
114, 867 
116.632 
118. 197 
119.862 
121. 626 
123,091 
124, 113 
124, 974 
125. 770 
126,626 

127.  521 

128.  429 

129.  2.S7 
130,085 

114 

1885 

145 

1886 

175 

1887 

190 

1888 

217 

1889 

234 

1890 

242 

1891 - - 

249 

1892 

256 

1893 

288 

1894 

310 

1895 

350 

1896 

379 

1897 

406 

1898 

432 

1899 

495 

1900 --- 

556 

1901 

I  9, 431 
•  10, 033 
«  11.211 
«  11, 548 
112,882 
•13,445 
14.777 
15,590 
17, 157 
17,845 
18,083 
18,822 
18.496 
18,998 
19,228 
20,841 
22,046 
22,207 
22,340 
22,353 
22,694 
22,694 
22,802 
22.816 
23.125 
22,749 
23.177 
23,762 
24,202 
25,163 
26,075 
27.841 
27.342 
27,342 
27.342 
26.657 
25. 772 
25.790 

272 
283 
310 
313 
343 
351 
378 
392 
424 
433 
432 
443 
429 
435 
434 
463 
483 
480 
476 
470 
470 
463 
458 
451 
450 
437 
439 
444 
446 
458 
471 
499 
487 
483 
480 
465 
447 
444. 

618 

1902        

641 

1903            .- 

661 

1904 

683 

1905 

700 

1906 

715 

1907            

730 

1908               

762 

1909                     

840 

1910 

855 

1911 

861 

1912 

895 

1913 

905 

1914              . 

908 

931 

1916 

1,018 

1917 

1,088 

1918 

1,136 

1919.. _ 

1920        

1,162 
1. 170 

1921            

1,188 

1922 

1,191 

1923        .             

1,178 

1924                   

1,176 

1925                     

1,192 

1926 

1,111 

1927 

1.138 

1928                             

1.149 

1929 

1.176 

1930          -      .               

1.186 

1931         

1.245 

1932 

1933            

1.261 
1.250 

1934 

1.234 

1935       

1.230 

1936       

1.217 

1937 

1,209 

1938       

1.233 

Source:  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute,  U.  8.  Census  Bureau  and  Corporation  records. 

I  Partly  estimated 

•  Flp:ures  for  1934  and  subsequent  years  include  only  that  portion  of  capacity  of  steel  for  castings  used  by 
foundries  operated  by  companies  producing  steel  ingots. 
Capacity  data  are  as  of  January  1  of  each  year;  population  data  are  as  of  July  1  of  each  year. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13851 


STEEL  INGOT  CAPACITY  COMPARED  WITH  POPULATION 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPOKATION  SUBSIDIARIES  AND  TOTAL  UNITED  STATES 


.500-          ^-^- 

^ — rTTrrr 

M       J    .tOTALi 

i 

M 

P 

L 1 

1200        1  1  i 

000         Mi 

T 1      '^       -  CAPACITY 
1  j               |PER  CAPITA^, 

^ 

¥ 

1 

i 

"t4®i 

1! 

iil 

us.  STt 

CAPACir 

i-Jj 

1 

1 

i  1 

"T   1  Mlt 

-^Tr       iL 

.iiiiiii 

PER  CAP! 

44' 

ti 

300 +i     ilXk 

ili-i'-'-tti 

TT 

M 

TtttTTIj 

T^i 

^  ff"m  I 

iM   HI 

l'! 

liH 

i! 

ill 

!'  1 

1500 


'^%^ 


a><j>cio^ocn-3io^ci 


A-»f,  //OT  <■•  S»^  (--Jt  W  U  S  Ceniu!  ( 


The  increase  In  ingo>  cspftcity  of  U.  S.  St?el  Cofpora+ion  since  1901  hss 
roughly  l-ept  pace  wiih  fna  growth  in  population  of  the  United  States. 
Ingot  capaci+>/  of  the  roal  steel  incusfrs',  hcwaver.  has  Increased  mor« 
rapidly  +han  population. 


124491 — 41— pt.  26- 


13852 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONO.MIC  POWER 


Total  ingot  ■production — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  and  other  steel  producing 
companies 


Production  in  Thousands 
of  Gross  Tons 

U.S. 
Steel 

'"Tlf 
U.S. 

Year 

i 

Production  in  Thousand.- 
of  Gross  Tons 

U.S. 
Steel 

Year 

U.S. 
Steel 

Other 
Com- 
panies 

Total 
U.S. 

U.S. 
Steei 

Other 

Com- 
panies 

Total 
U.S. 

ln%of 
Total 
U.  S 

IflOl 

1902 

8,855 
9,760 
9,174 
8,413 
12,006 
13,529 
13,100 
7,839 
13, 355 
14, 179 
12,763 
16.001 
18. 6.56 
11,  826 
16,376 
20,911 
20,285 
19,583 
17,200 

4,618 
8,197 
5, 361 
4*4; 
8,018 
9, 8W 
10,  263 
6.184 
10,600 
11,916 
10,923 
14,350 

14,  646 
11,687 

15,  775 
21, 863 
24,  776 
24,879 
17, 471 

13, 473 
14, 947 
14,536 
13,360 
20,024 
23, 398 
23,363 
14,023 
23,905 
26.096 
23,676 
31, 251 
31,301 
23,  613 
32, 151 
42.  774 
45.061 
44,  462 
34, 671 

es.7 

66.2 
63.1 
60.7 
60.0 
57.8 
66.1 
56.9 
53.8 
64.3 
53.9 
St.! 
53.2 
50.3 
50.9 
48.9 
45.0 
44.0 
49.6 

1 

1  1920 

1  192!     

19, 278 
10,966 
16,082 
20,  33C 
16,  479 
18,899 
20,307 
18.486 
20,106 
21,869 
16,  726 
10, 0K2 
4,929 
8.04' 
8,  660 
11.131 
16,  9f/S 
18,532 
9, 307 

22,856 
8;818 
19,  521 
24,614 
21,453 
26,  495 
27,987 
26,4^3 
31,  438 
34.  .'VU 
2S.  'm 
15,  803 
8.  7:.2 
15,185 
1  17,375 
2-i,  962 
30, 860 
32,036 
18.953 

42,113  '            45.8 

1903 

1904 ... 

e:::::::: 

1907 

1908 

1905 

1910... 

1911.. 

1912 

1913 ... 

1914 

1916 . 

1916 

1917 

ma 

19i9 

1922 

1923. 

1924 

1925 

1926 

1927. 

1928. 

1929 

1930 

'  1531 . 

1932 

1333 

1934. 

1935.   - 

1936 

1937 

ffl 

35, «« 
44  944 
37  932 
4.S.  594 
48.  294 
44,  93-- 
51,544 
56,  '.33 
40,699 
25,046 
13,681 
23,  232 
'26,055 
34,093 
47,768 
.50,569 
28,350 

45.2 
45.2 
43.4 
41.6 
42.0 
41.2 
39.0 
38.8 
41.1 
38.9 
36.0 
34.6 
33.2 
32.6 
35.4 
36.6 
33.1 

fiourco:  Corporation  records  and  American  Iron  and  Stfiel  iDotitate.    Datii  iuclude  production  of  castings. 

'  .Figures  tor  19j4  and  subsequent  years  include  only  that  portiin  of  production  of  steel  for  castings  used 
by  fouQdrie.s  operated  by  companies  producing  steel  ingots. 

Tennessee  Coal,  Iron  and  Kaiiroad  Company  data  included  in  Cjrporation  figures  tegiDnins  will:  Jan- 
uary 1,  1908.     . 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13853 


TOTAL  INGOT  PRODUCTION 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  SUBSIDIARIES  AND  OTHER  STEEL  PRODUCING  COMPANIES 


- 

- 

s 

1 

U.S. 

> 

IMII 

STEEL  PROOUC 
IS  OF  TOTAL 

Tl 

5N 

S. 

S 

\ 

" 

J 

' 

- 

- 

^ 

- 

- 

- 

.. 

« 

■ 

- 

( 

1 

I 

^ 

I 

I 

I 

I 

I 

I 

3 

c 

^ 

i 

3 

0 

I 

3 

« 

? 

« 

I 

I 

I 

1 

3 

I 

1 

I 

^ 

I 

1 

1 

.•JCOrti  an</  After.  Iron  C^  Steci  ti 


ingot  production  has  shown  great  variation  from  year  to  year,  because  the 
demand  for  steel  products  fluctuates  so  widely  with  changes  in  general 
business  conditions. 

The  portion  of  the  country's  ingots  produced  by  U.  S.  Stee|  Corporation 
has  been  declining  with  few  interruptions  since  1901.  Whereas  the 
Corporation  produce  '  66%  of  the  total  in  J 90 1,  it  produced  but  33% 
in  1938. 


13854  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Steel  ingot  production  compared  with  populaiion-total  United  States 


1884.. 
1885.. 
1886.. 
1887.. 


1900. 
1901. 
1902. 
1903. 
1904. 
1905. 
1906. 
1907. 
1908. 
1909. 
1910. 


Produc- 
tion 
(Thou- 
sands of 
Gross 
Tons) 


Popula- 
tion 
(Ttou- 
sands) 


1,551 
1,712 
2,563 
3,339 
2,899 
3,386 
4,277 
3,904 
4,928 
4,020 
4,412 
6,115 
6,282 
7,157 
8,933 
10,640 
10,188 
13,474 
14,947 
14,635 
13,860 
20,024 
23, 398 
23,363 
14,023 
23,955 
26,095 

mi::::::::::::.— 1  23,676 


Produc- 
tion 
per 
Capita 
(Pounds) 


55,  S 

56,658 

57,938 

69,217 

60,496 

61, 775 

63,056 

64,361 

65,666 

66.970 

68,275 

69,580 

70,885 

72, 189 

73,494 

74,799 

76,129 

77, 747 

79,3(65 

80,983 

82,601 

84,219 

85,837 

87,455 

89,073 

90,691 

92,267 


1925.. 
1926.. 
1927. 
1928. 
1929. 
1930. 
1931. 
1932. 
1933. 
1934. 
1935. 


Ingot 
Produc- 
tion 
(Thou- 
sands of 
Gross 
Tons) 


Popula- 
tion 
(Thou- 
sands) 


Produc- 
tion 
per 
Capita 
(Pounds) 


31, 251 
31,301 
23,513 
32, 151 
42, 774 
45,061 
44,462 
34,671 
42, 133 
19,784 
35,603 
44,944 
37, 932 
45,394 
48,294 
44, 935 
51,544 
56,433 
40,699 
25,946 
13,681 
23,232 
1  26, 055 
34,093 
47,768 

1937'::::::::: 50, 669 


95,097 
96,512 
97,928 
99,343 
100,758 
102, 173 


109, 873 
111,537 
113,202 
114,867 
116,532 
118, 197 
119,862 
121,  626 
123, 091 
124, 113 
124,974 
125,  770 
126, 628 
127,  521 
128,429 
129,257 
130,085 


927 
851 
963 
,039 
741 
468 
244 
414 
461 
599 
833 
876 


mZs  for  1934  and  subseauent  years  include  only  that  portion  of  production  of  steel  for  c^stmgs  used 
by  fortes  operated  by  companies  producing  steel  ingots. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13856 


STEEL  INGOT  PRODUCTION  COMPARED  WITH  POPULATION 


rOTAL  UNITED  STATES 

1                      ^i 

INGO                 , 
PRODUCTION    /W 

( 

an     _      - 

Ml 

!\ 

yllt-M 

ji^f'-  T POPULATION 

y 

iiiiiiiiiii 

iiiiiiiiiiiiiiiiii 

200    § 
150    ^ 


1200 
1000 
800 


iiiisslsigmg^sgSgSggfgaSISI 


:  Amtr.  Inn  O-Su^liA  vdU.S.  C  ,«  ( 


From  1884  thrpugh  1929,  steel  ingot  production  in  this  country  expanded 
more  rapidly  than  population  and  production  per  capita  increased  from  63 
to  1,039  pounds.  Since  1929,  the  situation  has  been  reversed;  the  peak  in 
1937  was  lower  than  that  of  1929  and  in  1938  production  was  only  488 
pounds  per  capita. 


13856  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Ingot  capacity  and  production —  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries 
[Monthly  Production  and  Average  Monthly  Capacity  in  Thousands  of  Grass  Tons] 


1920 

1923 

1926 

1929 

1932 

1936 

1938 

Jan 

1,676 
1,630 
1,858 
1,468 
1,548 
1,522 
1,415 
1,500 
1,569 
1,658 
1,685 
1,769 

1.780 
1,560 
1,809 
1,755 
1,865 
1,694 
1,660 
1,738 
1,599 
1,778 
1,616 
1,476 

1,701 
1,634 
1,996 
1,812 
1,721 
1,637 
1,631 
1,711 
1,651 
1,668 
1.553 
1,593 

1,753 
1,733 
1,975 
2.019 
2,142 
1,970 
1,982 
2,009 
1,772 
1,754 
1,495 
1,266 

661 
549 
569 
457 
432 
342 
263 
291 
361 
392 
376 
348 

909 

957 

879 

899 

753 

7.S8 

923 

951 

1,039 

1,070 

1,059 

685 

Feb 

548 

Mar - 

Apr                                   -          

711 
642 

Sfay                                       - -- 

647 

587 

Jul       . 

612 

Aug                                           

764 
838 

Oct -. 

1,047 

Nov - 

1,224 

Dec 

1,092 

Aver.  Cap'y                .                .  . 

1,863 

1,900 

1,899 

2,017 

2,320 

2,278 

2,143 

1921 

1924 

1927 

1930 

1933 

1936 

1939 

Jan 

1,803 
1,349 
1,103 
760 
743 
612 
501 
622 
648 
939 
978 
919 

1,736 
1,738 
1,934 
1.529 
1,206 
1,015 
876 
1,120 
1,227 
1,316 

Mn 

1,466 

1,695 
1.649 
1.993 
1.780 
1,781 
1  492 
1,328 
1,446 
1,311 
1,335 
1,339 
1,339 

1,480 
1,652 
1,792 
1,690 
1.719 
1.489 
1.283 
1.382 
1,340 
1,140 
905 
854 

350 
349 
305 
466 
655 
926 
1,204 
1,000 
790 
785 
569 
648 

997 
1,037 
1,215 
1,472 
1,515 
1,473 
1,409 
1,534 
1,490 
1,590 
1.578 
1.598 

1,076 

Feb 

1,037 

Mar " ::    

1,177 

1,018 

mi"            :::::::::::::;:::::::: 

963 

988 

Jul - -..:_- 

1.047 

Aug - 

Oct 

Nov..... ...     

Dec 

Aver.  Cap'y 

1,891 

1.901 

1,931 

2,073 

2,278 

2,221 

2,143 

1922 

1925 

1928 

1931 

1334 

1937 

Jan 

962 
1,048 
1,  3.59 
1,346 
1,446 
1,456 
1.359 
1,279 
1,246 
1,493 
1,553 
1,634 

1,832 
1,674 
1,859 
1,578 
1,440 
1,401 
1,348 
1,461 
1,472 
1,699 
1,613 
1,623 

1,657 
1,715 
1.882 
1,792 
1,731 
1.498 
1.497 
1,606 
1.633 
1.821 
1.669 
1,616 

1,042 

1,013 

1,241 

1,134 

997 

837 

743 

661 

597 

608 

642 

667 

602 
693 
917 
976 
1,194 
1,162 
536 
616 
487 
461 
608 
618 

1.738 
T  639 

1,964 
1,865 
1,695 
1,790 
1,603 
1,131 
800 
552 

Feb... -. 

Mar 

Apr 

Jun 

m 

Aug          --          

Oct - - 

Nov --- 

Dec 

1,891 

1,927 

1.080 

2,240 

2,278 

2,148 

Data  include  Ingots  and  castings. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13857 


INGOT  CAPACITY  AND  PRODUCTION 

U  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  SUBSIDIARIES 
MILLIONS  OF  GROSS  TONS 


1920        1922        1924 


1930       1932        1934        1936 


Ai  four  di'tmcf  peiiods  m  the  inrervai  1920  1929,  denands  upon  Ingot 
production  facilities  exceeded  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  s  capacity.  About 
1929  the  Corporation  inaugurated  a  prorjiarn  of  plant  ^nodern;za^ion 
which  was  accompanied  by  an  increase  in  ingof  capacity.  Having  been 
commenced,  this  program  wa;  carried  on  during  the  years  1930-1932  in 
spite  of  the  business  depression,  the  magnitude  and  duration  of  which 
could  not  be  foreseen. 

Since  1932,  some  obsolete  capacity  has  been  retired.  At  preosnt.  the  ingot 
capacity  of  the  Corporation  is  no  mere  than  sufficient  tc  provide  the 
steel  which  it  required  at  periods  of  peak  demand. 


13858  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Ingot  capacity  and  production — total  United  States 
[Monthly  Production  and  Average  Monthly  Capacity  in  Thousands  of  Gross  Tons] 


1920 

1923 

1926 

1929 

1932 

1935 

1938 

Jan 

3.624 
3,402 
3,917 
3,132 
3;  423 
3,539 
3,328 
3,562 
3,561 
3,581 
3,133 
2,779 

3,841 
3,472 
4,067 
3,964 
4,216 
3,767 
3,631 
3,696 
3,357 
3,5<7 
3,134 
2,863 

4,132 
3,785 
4,469 
4,196 
3,928 
3,734 
3,635 
3,987 
3,913 
4,074 
3,076 
3,467 

4,545 
4,372 
5,118 
4,999 
5,339 
4,951 
4,898 
4,988 
4,673 
4,579 
3,556 
2,932 

1,600 

1,496 

1,448 

1,273 

1,137 

923 

815 

856 

1,003 

1,099 

1,043 

871 

2,915 
2,817 
2,910 
2,682 
2,675 
2.294 
2,303 
2,962 
2,869 
3,192 
3,200 
3,121 

1,794 

Feb 

1,726 

Mar """ 

2,038 

Apr 

1,951 

May :   : 

1,831 

jun                    . 

1,660 

Jul  .               

2,008 

2,580 

se^v:::::::   ::::::::::::::: :::::::::: 

2,692 

Oct 

3,158 

Nov 

3,618 

Dec 

3,185 

Aver,  cap'y 

4,636 

4,887 

4,818 

5,315 

5,862 

5,837 

5,966 

1921 

1924 

1927 

1930 

1933 

1936 

1939 

Jan.  , 

2,517 
1,999 
1,795 
1,387 
1,446 
1,146 
918 
1,300 
1,342 
1,847 
1,897 
1,630 

3,650 
3,826 
4,207 
3,348 
2,640 
2  066 
1,878 
2,553 
2,828 
3,125 
3,121 
3,569 

3,823 
3,S45 
4.575 
4,163 
4.083 
3,626 
3,232 
3,529 
3,298 
3,345 
3,155 
3,203 

3,808 
4,067 

t;!l 

4,014 
3,445 
2,945 
3,085 
2,863 
2,714 
2,2.30 
1,995 

1,030 
1,087 
910 
1,361 
2,005 
2,599 
3,210 
2,905 
2,313 
2,112 
1,540 
1,822 

3,086 
3,002 
3,384 
3,991 
4,097 
4,035 
3,975 
4.247 
4,214 
4,601 
4,389 
4,491 

3,225 

Feb... - 

3,037 

Mar — ..: 

3,459 

Ap' 

3,021 

May 

2,970 

Jun 

3,175 

Jul                                                         .           . 

3,214 

Aug                                       

3,823 

4,299 

Oct 

6,480 

Nov 

5:551 

Dec - 

5,246 

Aver.  Cap'y 

4,781 
1922 

4,953 

5,003 

5,431 

5,849 

6,816 

6,088 

1925 

1928 

1931 

1934 

1937 

Jan 

2' 071 
2,814 
2,902 
3,219 
3,128 
2,953 
2,629 
2,818 
3,410 
3,430 
3,301 

4,193 
3,752 
4,194 
3,584 
3.455 
3,205 
3,084 
3,421 
3,490 

4,028 
4,081 
4,549 
4,345 
4.246 
3,778 
3,841 
4,217 
4,186 
4,693 
4,306 
4,055 

2,534 
2,570 
3,083 
2,794 
2,574 
2,149 
1,907 
1,733 
1,560 
1,605 
1,607 
1,313 

2, 025 
2,243 
2.836 
2,976 
3,447 
3,102 
1.509 
1,399 

i;502 
1,633 
1,991 

4,786 
4.498 
5,303 
5,155 
5,237 
4,254 
4,631 
4,958 
4,362 
3,449 
2,189 
1,496 

Feb " "" ""  ' 

Mar                             -                

uii:      :::"::::::::::::::::::::: 

Jul 

Aug 

Sep 

Oct " 

1^:::::::::::::::::::::::: :::::::::;::: 

Dec 

4,868 

5,095 

6,122 

6,748 

6,813 

6,815 

Data  include  production  of  open-hearth,  Bessemer,  crucible  and  electric  ingots,  but  exclude  production  of 
castings.  Portion  of  the  1939  monthly  data  represented  by  production  of  crucible  and  electric  ingots  was 
estimated. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13859 

Percent  of  ingot  capacity  operated — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries 


Year 

Average 

Rate  for 

Year 

Peak  Month 

Average 
Rate- 
Peak 
Month 

1920 

86.2 
48.3 
70.9 
89.2 
72.2 
81.7 
89.3 
79.8 
84.7 
90.4 
66.5 

n'.7 

29.4 
31.6 
40.8 
63.4 
72.0 
36.4 
51.9 

March 

96.0 

1921 

January 

95.7 

82.0 

May 

94.8 

March _ 

102.2 

192S     

March _ 

96.8 

1926 - 

March 

97.5 

1927 

March 

95.6 

1928 

March  . 

1929 

May 

98  3 

1930 

March..  . 

82.9 

1931 

March 

64.9 

1932 

March 

22.7 

1933 

July 

55.1 

May .■ 

47.0 

72.0 

1937 

May 

89.7 

1938 

57.7 

19391 

September 

67  6 

Per  cent  of  ingot  capacity  operated  Is  based  on  ingots  and  castings. 
Peak  month  rate  is  calculated  from  actual  monthly  capacity. 

'  First  9  months. 


i386C 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


PER  CENT  OF  INGOT  CAPACITY  OPERATED 

ANNUAL  AVERAGE  CONTRASTED  WITH  PEAK  MONTH 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  SUBSlDlARltS 


i  rOS  1953  ARE  c<  e\sis  '. 


In  the  steel  business  it  is  imperat've  that  there  be  sufficient  capacity  to 
meet  peak  demands.  Customers'  orders  vary  as  to  s-ze  f\n6  quali+y  to  such 
an  extent  that  steel  must  be  rolled  to  order  and  cannot  ordinarily  be  talcen 
from  stock.  Some  steel  products,  such  as  sheets  A'hich  a'e  to  be  subjected 
to  deep-drawing  as  in  ihe  manufacture  of  autoniobile  fenders,  m^jst  bs 
used  in  a  comparatively  short  time  after  production  in  order  to  obtain  the 
best  results. 

The  extent  to  which  the  curve  representing  peak  monthly  operations  is 
above  the  curve  representing  average  operations  is  an  indication  of  the 
extent  to  which  the  capacity  needed  to  meet  peak  demands  even  in  years 
of  low  production  is  in  excess  of  the  average  capacity  operated.  It  is 
apparent  that  the  entire  amount  of  the  capacity  of  the  United  States  Steel 
Corporation  subsidiaries  is  needed  to  meet  peak  demanoi  in  prosperous 
yeers. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13861 


steel  production  and  manufacturing  production- Federal  Reserve  indexes  adjusted 
for  seasonal  variation 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec- 


Jan.. 
Feb.. 
Mar.. 
Apr.. 
May. 
Jun.. 
Jul... 
Aug.. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov.. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb.. 
Mar- 
Apr.. 
May. 
Jun.. 
Jul... 
Aug.. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov.. 
Dec. 


Mfrg 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May. 
Jun.. 
Jul... 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb.. 
Mar.. 
Apr.. 
May. 
Jun.. 
Jul... 
Aug.. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov- 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb.. 
Mar.. 

May. 
Jun.. 
Jul... 
Aug.. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov.. 
Dec. 


[1923-1925  =  100] 


Mfrg 


Jan., 
Feb- 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.- 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.- 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec 


Jan.. 
Feb.. 
Mar.. 
Apr.. 
May. 
Jun.. 
Jul... 
Aug.. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov.. 
Dec. 


Feb.. 
Mar.. 
Apr.. 
May. 
Jun.. 
Jul... 
Aug.. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov.. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb.. 

Mar. 


May. 
Jun.. 
Jul... 
Aug.. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov.. 
Dec. 


Steel       Mfrg 


Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec 


29 

63 

31 

61 

22 

M 

36 

66 

48 

77 

71 

03 

99 

102 

«0 

01 

«fi 

83 

60 

76 

47 

70 

60 

73 

Jan. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


13862  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Steel  production  and  manufacturing  production — Federal  Reserve  indexes  adjusted 
for  seasonal  variation — Continued 

[1923-1925-100] 


Steel 

Mfrg 

Steel 

Mfrg 

Steel 

Mfrg 

1938 

Jul 

1938 

Jan 

1939 

Jan 

62 
50 
49 
50 
47 
46 

76 
75 
76 
73 
73 
74 

62 
70 
76 
90 
108 
101 

82 
87 
89 
95 
103 
104 

94 

87 

79 
73 
89 
100 

100 

Feb 

Aug 

Feb 

97 

Sep.. 

93 
91 

Apr... 

Oct 

^/y 

May 

Nov 

97 

Jun 

Dec    . 

Jul.. 

>  101 

Source:  Federal  Reserve  Board. 
>  Preliminary. 


STEEL  PRODUCTION  AND  MANUFACTURING  PRODUCTION 

FEDERAL  RESERVE  INDEXES  ADJUSTED  FOR  SEASONAL  VARIATION 

160  p^ 

1 

1 — 

19 

23- 

1925 

=  1 

DO 

1 

r" 

. — 

160 

140 

120 
to 

Z     100 

_ 

— 

— 

— 

/ 

^ 

— 

— 

— 

— 

— 

140 
120 
100     £ 

y 

u 

k 

^ 

^ 

MANUFACTURING 
PRODUCTION 

\ 

\ 

/ 

, 

\i 

5 

i    80 

\ 

^ 

^ 

// 

\J 

80       i 

\ 

fv\ 

h 

\f 

\ 

2       60 

^       40 

20 

0 

\ 

SJ" 

/ 

60      2 

Q 

40       ? 
20 

I 

\ 

V 

./  IRON  AND  STEEL 
K      PRODUCTION 

1924        1926        1928        1930        1932        1934        1936        1938 

Soor,t     f«*.-y /?«»-»»  Soi'rf 

The  steel  business  in  the  United  States  is  good  when  general  business  is 
good  and  vice  versa.  There  is  marked  correlation  in  the  fluctuations  in 
steel  production  and  those  of  all  manufacturing  production,  although  the 
peaks  and  valleys  of  steel  production  are  somewhat  more  pronounced 
than  those  for  all  manufacturing. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13863 

World  ingot  production  by  principal  steel  producing  countries 


Production  in  Thou- 
sands of  Gross  Tons 

Country 

Production  in  Thou- 
sands of  Gross  Tons 

1929 

1937 

1938 

1929 

1937 

1938 

United  States 

56, 433 
18,786 
4,645 
9,636 

60,569 
20, 176 
17,  544 
12,964 

28,350 
22,876 
18,156 
10, 394 

,Tnpftn 

2,258 
9,546 
2,089 
4,015 

5,719 
7,795 
2,054 
3.808 

6  860 

Germany  • 

Fraqce 

6  077 

U.  S.S.  R 

Italy 

2,285 

United  Kingdom. 

2,249 

« Includes  Austria  but  not  Czechoslovakia. 

Source:  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute,  except  production  of  Japan,  1938,  estimated  by  Iron  Age 
(foreign  figures  based  on  information  received  from  abroad). 
Data  Include  production  of  steel  ingots  and  castings. 


UNITED 
STATES 


GERMANY 


U.S.S.R. 


FRANCE 


ITALY 


BELGIUM 


WORLD  INGOT  PRODUCTION 

BY  PRINCIPAL  STEEL  PRODUCING  COUNTRIES 

MILLIONS  OF  GROSS  TONS 
20  30  40 


'.  'ion  &  Slul  //at  tnd  Im  Agr 


The  United  States  produces  more  steel  than  any  other  country  In  the  world. 
In  the  last  ten  years,  however,  its  steel  production  has  declined,  while  that 
of  most  of  the  other  countries  has  increased,  notably  Germany  and  Russia. 


13864  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Ingot  capacity  and  production 
[Total  United  States] 


Month 
1920 

ly  Production  and  Average  Monthly  Capacity  in 
Thousands  of  Gross  Tons 

1923 

1926 

1929 

1932 

1935 

1938 

Jan 

3,624 
3,402 
3,917 
3,132 
3,423 
3,539 
3,328 
3,562 
3.661 
3,681 
3,133 
2,779 

3,841 
3,472 
4,067 
3.964 
4,216 
3,767 
3,531 
3,696 
3,357 
3,577 
3.134 
2,863 

4.132 

3,785 
4,469 
4,106 
3,928 
3,734 
3,635 
3.987 
3,913 
4,074 
3,076 
3,467 

4,  ,545 
4,372 
5,118 
4,999 
5,339 
4,961 
4,898 
4,988 
4,573 
4,579 
3,656 
2,932 

1,500 

1,496 

1,448 

1,273 

1,137 

923 

815 

856 

1,003 

1,099 

1,043 

871 

2,915 
2,817 
2,910 
2  682 
2.675 
2.294 
2.303 
2,962 
2.869" 
3.192 
3,200 
3,121 

1  764 

Feb 

1  726 

Mar 

2  038 

Apr                                             -  - 

1  951 

Xy" " 

jun                              .               

1,660 

Jul . 

2  008 

Auk                             .  -           

2,580 

Sep     : ...    

2,692 

Oct                                -           -. 

3,  158 

Nov                               

3,618 

Dec                 .           

3,185 

4,636 

4,887 

4,818 

6,315 

5,862 

5.837 

1921 

2,517 
1,999 
1,795 
1,387 
1,448 
1,146 
918 
1,300 
1,342 
1,847 
1,897 
1,630 

1924 

3,650 
3,826 
4,207 
3,348 
2,640 
2,066 
1,878 
2,653 

31125 
3,121 
3,569 

1927 

1930 

1933 

1,030 
1,087 
910 
1.361 
2.006 
2,599 
3,210 
2,905 
2,313 
2,112 
1,640 
1,822 

1936 

1939 

Jan  — --- 

Feb... - 

3.823 
3,846 
4.675 
4,163 
4,083 

3]  232 
3,529 
3.298 
3,345 
3,155 
3,203 

3.808 
4.067 

41142 
4,014 
3,445 
2,945 
3,085 
2,863 
2,714 
2.230 
1,995 

3,086 
3.002 
3.384 
3,991 
4,097 
4,035 
3,975 
4,241 
4,214 
4,601 

4!  491 

3.225 
3,037 

Mar... --- 

3,459 

Apr— - - 

3,021 

May..... — 

2,970 

Jun -- - 

3,175 

Jul 

30, 214 

Aug -.-- 

3,823 

Sep 

4.299 

Oct --.- 

5,480 

Nov.... -  - 

Pec 

5,551 
6,246 

Aver.  Cap'y 

4,781 

4,953 

5.003 

5,431 

6,849 

5,816 

6,088 

1922 

1925 

1928 

1931 

1934 

1937 

Jan               - ---- 

1,893 
2,071 
2.814 
2.902 
3,219 
3,128 
2,953 
2,629 

4,193 
3,752 
4,194 
3,584 
3.455 
3,205 
3,084 
3,421 
3,490 
3,889 
3,903 
3,971 

4,028 
4,081 
4,  549 
4,345 
4,246 
3,778 
3,841 
4,217 
4,186 
4.693 
4,306 
4,055 

2,534 
2,570 
3,083 
2,794 
2,574 
2,149 
1.907 
1,733 
1.660 
1,605 
1,607 
1,313 

2,025 
2,243 
2,836 
2,976 
3,447 
3,102 
1,509 
1.399 
1,286 
1,602 
1,633 
1,991 

4,786 
4,498" 
5.303 
5.155 
5,237 
4,254 
4,631 

4!  362 
3,449 
2,189 
1,496 

Feb - - 

Mar --- 

Apr 

Sfay. 

Jan.: 

Jul 

Aug 

Se^. 

2,818 
3,410 
3,430 
3,301 

c^:::..., 

Nov - ---. 

Dec - 

Aver.  Cap'y 

4,868 

5,095 

5,122 

5,748 

5,813 

5.815 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13865 


INGOT  CAPACITY  AND  PRODUCTION 

TOTAL  UNITED  STATES 

MILLIONS  OF  GROSS  TONS 

6 
5 
4 
3 

6 
5 
4 
3 

X' 

._j 



"a 

M 

VERA 
ONTH 
*PAC 

t 
LY 
TY 

H 

-- 

1 

'" 

ik 

1 

L 

k 

Ai* 

^ 

A 

/ 

\ 

Vj 

n 

i^ 

^ 

1 

V 

'^ 

% 

L 

Ipi  oduc 

TION 

i 

i 

r/ 

L 

i 

1 

2 

— 

\ 

I- 

4 

— 

— 

r 

\ 

V 

f 

I 
1 

u 

-" 

J- 

' 

2 

1 
0 

0 

- 

V. 

1920       1922       1924       1926       1928       1930       1932       1934       1936       1938 

SLrre;  American  /ran  &  Sl^l  hstitiM 

Capacity  of  the  steel  Industry  is -not  excessive.  Unused  or  Idle  capacity 
should  not  be  confused  with  "excess"  capacity.  Ingot  copacity,  an  accepted 
basis  for  determining  rotes  of  operations,  reflects  roughly  operations  of 
finishing  capacities.  Even  in  periods  of  peak  demand;  orders  are  not  dis- 
tributed among  products  in  such  a  way  as  to  make  possible  full  utilization 
of  all  finishing  facilities.  In  practice,  therefore,  operations  probably  would 
never  be  maintained  ot  100  per  cent  of  either  ingot  or  finishing  capacity 
because  of  lack  of  coordination  between  demand  and  capacity  for  various 
products.  Production  might,  therefore,  be  expected  to  run  below  capacity 
even  at  the  peak  of  the  cycle. 

In  times  of  emergency,  or  under  the  pressure  of  extraordinary  demands  on' 
the  industry,  it  might  occasionally  be  possible  to  attain  an  operating  rate 
slightly  in  excess  of  100  per  cent  of  rated  capacity  for  short  periods  by 
bringing  into  operotion  obsolete  facilities,  lengthening  the  work  week, 
eliminating  holidays,  or  by  other  means. 


13866  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Section  E — Labor 
Number  of  employees  and  ingot  production — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


(000  Omitted) 

Index  No.'s 
1929=100 

(000  Omitted) 

Index  No.'s 
1929=100 

No.  of 
Empl'8 

Ingot 

Prod'n 

(Or. 

Tons) 

Empl's 

Prod'n 

No.  of 
Empl's 

Ingot 

Prod'n 

(Or. 

Tons) 

Empl's 

Prod'n 

1929 

Jan 

1933 

Jon 

243 

244 
24"; 
255 
259 
261 
263 
263 
260 
265 
248 
241 

1,753 
1,733 
1,975 
2,019 
2,142 
1,970 
1,982 
2,009 
i:772 
1,754 
1,495 
1,266 

96 
96 
97 
101 
102 
103 
104 
104 
103 
101 
98 
95 

96 
95 
108 
111 
118 
108 
109 
110 
97 
96 
82 
69 

151 
147 
140 
144 
151 
171 
190 
201 
201 
190 
192 
189 

350 
349 
305 
466 
655 
926 
1,204 
1.000 
790 
785 
569 
648 

60 
68 
65 
67 
60 
67 
76 
79 
79 
76 
76 
76 

19 

Feb 

Feb 

19 

Mar 

Apr 

Mar. 

Apr 

17 
26 
36 
51 

Jun 

May 

Jun 

Jill 

Jul 

6fl 
66 

Aug 

Aug 

Sep 

Sep 

43 

oc?: :::::::: 

Oct 

g?J-::::::: 

Nov 

Dec... 

31 

Jan 

19 

30 

1934 

Jan 

242 
248 
252 
256 
261 
262 
259 
256 
253 
248 
244 

1,480 
1,652 
1,792 
1,690 
1,719 
1,489 
1,283 
1,382 
1,340 
1,140 
905 
854 

96 
98 
)0f 
10 
10b 
103 
102 
101 
100 
98 
96 
94 

81 
91 

93 
94 
81 
70 
76 
74 
62 
49 
47 

185 
187 
190 
195 
■604 
208 
203 
192 
186 
178 
176 
174 

602 
693 
917 
976 
1,194 
1,152 
536 
516 
487 
461 
508 
618 

73 
74 
75 
77 
81 
82 
80 
76 
73 
'0 
70 
69 

33 

Feb"" 

Feb 

38 

Mar 

Apr 

Mar_ 

Apr 

50 

/ay 

Jun 

May 

Jun 

66 
63 

j"l ■■ 

Jul 

29 

Aug 

Aug 

28 

Sep. 

Sep. 

27 

Oct 

Oct.... 

25 

^tlv"-::: 

Nov 

Dec 

28 
34 

Jan 

1931 

1935 

Jan 

238 
237 
237 
237 
233 
221 
207 
203 
199 
194 
192 
189 

1,042 

1,013 

1,241 

1,134 

997 

837 

743 

661 

597 

608 

642 

567 

94 
94 
94 
94 
92 
87 
82 
80 
79 
77 
76 
75 

67 
56 
68 
62 
54 
46 
41 
36 
33 
33 
35 
31 

182 
191 
195 
196 
197 
197 
196 
197 
197 
190 
198 
196 

909 
933 

957 

879 

899 

753 

758 

923 

951 

1,039 

1,070 

1,059 

72 
75 

77 
78 
78 
78 
77 
78 
78 
77 
78 
77 

60 

Feb 

Feb 

51 

Mm":::::::: 

Apr 

Mar 

Apr 

63 

48 

/ay 

Jun 

May 

Jun 

49 
41 

Jul..... 

Jul. 

43 

Aug ■. 

61 

Sep :. 

Sep 

62 

Oct :: 

Oct....:... 

67 

g^c^v.:::::: 

g^I".::-:-:: 

59 
58 

Jan 

Feb 

19 

32 

19 

36 

Jan 

186 
182 
182 
173 
167 
169 
165 
150 
152 
154 
158 
164 

551 
549 
669 
457 
432 
342 
263 
291 
361 
392 
376 
348 

73 
72 
72 
68 
66 
63 
61 
69 
80 
61 
62 
61 

30 
30 
31 
25 

14 
16 
20 
22 
20 
10 

196 
197 
201 
211 
220 
223 
229 
235 
238 
239 
240 
239 

997 
1,037 
1,215 
1,472 
1.515 
1,473 
1,409 
1,534 

\:Z 

77 
78 
79 
83 
87 
88 
91 
93 
94 
94 
95 
94 

55 

Feb 

57 

Mar 

Apr 

Mar 

Apr 

67 
81 

May 

Jun 

May 

83 
81 

Jul 

Jul 

77 

Aug 

Aug 

84 

Sep    . 

Sep 

82 

Oct     . 

Oct 

87 

Nov 

Dec 

To".:::::: 

87 
88 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13867 

Number  of  employees  and  ingot  jtrodudion — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  end  eubsid- 
iaries — Continued 


(000  Omitted) 

Index  No.'8 
1929-100 

(000  Omitted) 

Index  No.'s 
1929=100 

No.  of 
Empl'8 

Ingot 
Prod'n 

(Or. 
Tons) 

Empl's 

Prod'n 

No.  of 
Empl's 

Ingot 
Tons) 

Empl's 

Prod'n 

1937 

Jul.. 

1938 

Jan 

240 
24fi 
2(4 
261 
267 
273 
277 
278 
276 
271 
266 
236 

1;1 

1,964 
1,866 
1,696 
1,790 
1,603 

■•IS 

662 

96 
97 

^ 

106 
108 
109 
110 
109 
107 
101 
93 

06 
90 
104 
102 
108 
102 
93 
98 
88 
62 
44 
30 

192 
191 
192 
107. 
206 
207 

612 

764 

838 

1,047  . 

1,224 

1,002 

76 
76 
76 
78 
81 
82 

34 

Frt" 

AoK.. 

42 

M« 

Sep.:: — 

^: . — 

67 

^ 

Nov 

Dec 

67 
60 

Jul 

Jan 

1939 

^^ 

Nov 

207 
209 
211 
196 
212 
214 
214 
214 
236 

1,076 
i;037 
1,177 

'Sg 

968 
1,047 
1,269 
1,431 

82 
83 
83 
77 
84 
84 
86 
86 
93 

60 

Feb 

67 

.1938 

Mar 

Apr 

66 
66 

Afty 

Jun 

63 

220 
211 
206 
204 
202 
197 

685 

711 
642 
847 
887 

87 
83 
81 
8i 
80 
78 

38 
30 
39 
83 
SS 
33 

64 

Jan 

Jul 

87 

Feb 

Aug. 

Sep 

.70 

Mar 

78 

Apr 

Oct 

i^y 

Jun 

g"J.-.::::::: 

Number  of  employees  repreaents  number  on  rolls  during  each  month. 
Ingot  production  data  Include  production  of  iqgots  and  castings. 


124491.^41-  pt.  2« 


13868 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


NUMBER  OF  EMPLOYEES  AND  INGOT  PRODUCTION 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

1929  =  100 

140 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 F 1 il40 


k 

^ 

yn 

i^ 

\ 

\ 

MBERO 
PLOYEE 

/? 

^ 

^.j 

V 

\ 

\ 

K 

\. 

Si 

Xr- 

1 

i 

1 1 

\ 

\ 

N 

f^/ 

J 

! 

/ 
/ 

\' 

V 

\r 

r 

VlNGOT 
-PR  DUCTIO 

fN 

y 

1 

1929    1930   1931    1932    1933    193!*    1935    1936    1937    1938    1939   1940 


During  depression  periods,  the  number  of  employees  of'U.  S.  Steel  Cor- 
poration has  not  declined  os  much  as  ingot  production.  To  a  large 
extent,  this  has  been  due  to  the  Corporotion's  policy  of  sharing  the 
available  work  so  far  as  practicable  among  the  maximum  number  of 
employees. 


In  1937,  there  were  more  employees  than  i 
ingot  production  was  less. 


1929.  despite  the  fact  that 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13869 


Actual  number  of  employees  and  number  that  would  have  been  required  on  basis  of 
1929  hours  per  week — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Actual 

No.of 
Empi's 

(B^l'l, 
HrsJ 

Addtl. 
Number 
Empl'd 

Actual 
No.of 
Empi's 

Empi's 
(Basis  '20 

Addtl. 
Number 
Empl'd 

253,138 
251,782 
215,223 
164,390 

263,138 
335,978 
160^020 
00,340 

Mar 

1036 

1930 

16,804 

'55'iSi 

73,990 

200,700 
211,008 
210,664 
222,079 
239,452 
234,972 
237, 570 
238,044 
340,014 
238,781 

162,044 
184,975 
180,234 
197,882 
195, 183 
190. 370 
'209,802 
216,670 
209,363 
209,838 

38,656 

Apr 

M;033 

1933 

Jun 

25  097 

jSf.".::::::::::::::: 

34,369 

151,010 
147,360 
130,686 
143,022 
160,661 
170,767 
100,170 
200,740 
200,633 
189,696 
102,438 
180)220 

77,703 
81,659 
78,116 
80,061 
97,173 
130,478 
163,947 
160,773 
138,967 
129,338 
119, 128 
120,418 

73,217 
66,710 
66,460 
63,861 
63,478 
.     40289 
36^223 
30^076 
61,666 
60  357 
73,310 
68,811 

Aug 

35,602 

JiuiuBrv 

Sep 

27,768 

Feb 

Oct 

23,374 

Mar 

Nov 

30,661 

Anr 

Dec : 

38.943 

^fi^::::::::::::: 

Jan 

1937 

Jul 

Aog 

S^D 

240,360 
244,602 
264,011 
260,665 
267,052 
272,656 
276,897 
278,178 
276,202 
270, 616 
255,788 
235,565 

207,683 
222,365 
220,810 
230,673 
228,902 
239,606 
230,748 
231,815 
228,378 
194,982 
167,767 
142,367 

oSt '  " 

32.776 

Feb 

22,337 

Dm :: 

Mar,. 

24,102 

Apr 

29,892 

1034 

May 

38,160 

Jun. 

33,060 

Jul..-. 

4o;i4e 

185,433 
186,686 
190,163 

JHeeo 

204,033 
207,731 
203,416 
192,038 
186,003 
178,426 
175,737 
174,350 

118,688 
126,074 
186,824 
188,207 
165,805 
162,318 
119,760 
116,803 
103, «« 
106,692 
104,986 
104, 157 

71,846 
60,612 
54.320 
56,462 
«,138 
46,413 
83,656 
76,236 
81,904 
71,834 
70,761 
70,108 

Aug 

46,363 

Jan 

Sep........ 

47.827 

Feb 

0(?t 

75,633 

Mar -.. 

Nov... 

88,031 

Apr - 

Dec 

93,308 

»fty-...- 

Jan 

Jtm. 

1938 

Jul.... - 

Aug 

Sep. ..:„. 

Oct 

220,270 
210,680 
204,810 
203,816 
201,623 
106,808 
102,021 
101,811 
103,321 
107,271 
206.700 
307,370 

120,683 
126,257 
130,830 
126.730 
120,014 
120,611 
111,389 

glS 

138, 773 
163,614 
149,468 

90,687 

Nov 

Feb 

84  323 

Dec 

Mm-' 

74  4% 

Apr 

78,085 

1935 

Jun 

76,287 

jt::::::::::::: 

80.633 

181,825 

ii 
lOsiftlO 

106,634 
106, 624 
106,685 
197,084 
106,075 

Its 

1«^02S 

%% 

144,210 
142,601 
151, 134 
140, 650 
1481800 

63.131 
45^482 
61,060 
5%  676 
H232 
60^206 
60  876 
52:324 
54,023 
44,461 
48^426 
4?;  086 

Aug 

67, 911 

Jan 

Sep : 

62,443 

Feb 

Oct 

ss,m 

Mar 

Nov 

62,095 

Apr 

Deo :    :: 

6/,  902 

*^:::::::::::::: 

Jan 

Jun 

1030 

JuL 

Aug 

Sep 

206,715 
208,005 
211,011 
105,764 
212,381 
213,728 
214,205 

148,648 

141.050 
146,644 
150. 139 
149.758 

Ort 

68,167 

Feb 

50,213 

Mar 

40,784 

Apr 

63,814 

193P 

64,689 

Jul 

64.447 

Jan.               .     .. 

196,858 
197, 4«3. 

152,617 
163,608 

43,241 
33,766 

Feb        .    .  

Actual  number  of  employees  represents  number  on  rolls  during  each  month. 

Equivalent  number  of  employees  was  obtained  by  multiplying  the  actual  n     _    .  

year  or  month  by  number  of  hours  worked  per  week  during  the  period  and  dividing  by  the  number  of 


;  the  actual  number  of  employees  in  esch 


hours  worked  per  week  daring  1929. 


13&70 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEB 


ACTUAL  NUMBER  OF  EMPLOYEES 

&  NUMBER  THAT  WOULD  HAVE  BEEN  REQUIRED  ON  BASIS  OF  1929  HOURS  PER  WEEK 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

250,000 
200,000 

A 

250,000 
200,000 
150,000 
100,000 
50,000 

-^ 

\» 

TUAL 
M8ER 

A 

■^ 

h 

\y 

f 

\ 

V 

Jl 

A 

r'- 

/ 

\/ 

(\f^ 

\ 

\ 

t 

A 

rv/l       1 

EQUW.  NUMBER 
ON  BASIS  OF  1929 
HOURS  PER  WEEK 

^y 

V 

V. 

J 

0 

ADDITIO 
100,000 

1929    1930    1931    1932    1933    1934    1935    1936   1937    1938    1939    1940   " 
^AL  NUMBER  OF  EMPLOYEES  DUE  TO  REDUCTION  OF  HOURS  PER  WEEK 

^ 

^ 

\/ 

^r 

./v 

/ 

K 

>A 

50,000 
0 

0 

ANNUAL  DATA  ir 

/ 

/ 

\j 

^ 

y 

1929   1930    1931    1932   1933    1934    1935    1936    1937    1938    1939    1940 

>9-l932,  MONTHIY  DATA  IHEREAntR 

U.  S.  Steel  Corporfttion's  policy  during  recent  depression  years  of  sharing 
the  available  work  so  far  as  practicable  among  the  maximum  number  of 
employees  has  made  it  possible  to  give  work  to  a  larger  number  of 
employees  than  would  otherwise  be  required.  The  additional  number  of 
employees  has  varied  from  a  minimum  of  about  25,000  during  periods  of 
high  operating  activity  to  a  maximum  of  roughly  90,000  during  periods  of 
business  depression. 

Ingot  production  and  number  of  employees — U.  S.  Sted  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Item 


(0  months) 


1837  In  % 
0^1929 


Monthly  Ingot  Production  (Tons). 

Number  of  Employees 

Hours  per  Week. 


Earnings  per  Hour.. 
Ettnlngs  per  Week. 


1,822,401 

2^3,138 

47.2 

10.643 

$3a33 


1,783,291 

263,391 

39.6 

lasie 

133.16 


Ingot  production  represents  average  monthly  production  of  Ingots  and  castings. 
Number  of  employees  represents  the  average  number  on  rolls. 

Hours  per  week,  earnings  per  hour  and  earnings  per  week  data  are  for  all  wage  earners  of  U.  8.  Steel  Cor- 
poration and  subsidiaries. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13871 


INGOT  PRODUCTION  AND  NUMBER  OF  EMPLOYEES 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
1929  =  100 

INGOT  NUMBER  OF 

PRODUCTION  EMPLOYEES 

•100 


loo- 


se- 


60- 


40- 


20- 


-60 


-40 


20 


1929  1937 


1929  1937 


TECHNOLOGICAL  ADVANCES  HAVE  NOT  RESULTED  IN 
FEWER  EMPLOYEES 


Technological  advances  in  the  art  of  steel  making  have  no+  resulted  in  fev^er  em- 
ployees being  required  by  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation.  The  year  1929  and  the  first  nine 
months  of  1937  are  two  periods  in  which  production  of  steel  was  comparable.  Be- 
tween these  two  periods  the  Corporation  expended  huge  amounts  for  mor§  modern 
and  continuous  types  of  equipment  to  keep  pace  with  technological  advances. 

Average  monthly  ingot  production  in  the  first  nine  months  of  1937  was  2%  less 
than  in  the  year  1929,  whereas  the  average  number  of  employees  in  the  first  nine 
months  of  1937  was  4%  more.  The  employees  in  1937  worked  about  8  hours  less  per 
week  than  in  1929  but.  due  to  increases  of  about  27%  in  hourly  wage  rates,  actu- 
ally earned  more  per  week  in  1937  than  In  1929. 


13872  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Ingot  production  and  number  of  employees — Total  steel  industry 


Monthly  Ingot  Production  (Tons). 
Number  of  Employees 


4.670,869 
428,319 


1937  (9 
months) 


1937  in  % 
or  1929 


Ingot  production  represents  average  monthly  production  of  all  ingots,  and  excludes  production  of  castings. 

Number  of  employees  represents  number  of  wage  earners  of  iron  and  steel  manufacturing  companies 
reporting  to  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute  (1929  figure  partially  estimated,  based  on  data  of  U.  S.  Census 
of  Manufactures  on  wage  earners  in  Blast  Furnaces,  Steel  Works  and  Rolling  Mills). 

Employment  and  payroll  by  classes  of  employees — U.  S.   Steel   Corporation   and 
subsidiaries 


Class  o(  Employees 

Number  of 
Employees 

Total  PayroU 

Wage  Earners:^ 

228,281 
170,241 

$366, 610. 690 

1938 

204,643,987 

Average                                                                 -  

199,261 

280, 627, 289 

Operating  Salaried: 

1937                                 . .:.. 

22,669 
21, 791 

$65, 938, 276 

1938.                                 -     

49, 311, 604 

22,230 

52, 624, 940 

Qen'l  Administrative  and  Sales: 

1937                                                                                                          -     . 

10, 343 
10,076 

$30,478,817 

1938                                                                                                             

28,353,741 

Average                                  -.    - 

10, 210 

29,  416,  279 

Number  of  employees  represents  the  average  number  on  rolls  during  the  year. 
Payroll  figures  include  construction  payroll. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13873 


EMPLOYMENT  AND  PAYROLL  BY  CLASSES  OF  EMPLOYEES 


U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
1937-1938  AVERAGE 


THOUSANDS  OF  EMPLOYEES 
50  100  150 


WAGE  EARNERS  199 

OPERATING  SALARIED    22 
GEN'L  ADMIN.  &  SALES    10 


WAGE  EARNERS  281 

OPERATING  SALARIED    53 
GEN'L  ADMIN.  &  SALES   29 


MILLIONS  OF  DOLWRS  OF  PAYROLL  PER  YEAR 

100  200  300 


General  administrative  and  sales  employees  receive  only  a  small  part 
of  the  total  payroll  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries.  During 
1937  and  1938  wage  earners  and  operating  salaried  employees,  repre- 
senting 957o  of  the  working  force,  received  927o  of  the  total  payroll. 


13874  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Employees  by  age  groups — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Age  Group 

Number  of 
Employees 

Per  Cent 
of  Total 

Ago  Group 

Number  of 
Employees 

Per  Cenl 
of  Total 

3/229 
21,409 
24,100 
25.771 
24,560 
26  207 
25,312 

1.7 
10.9 
12.3 
13.2 
1Z6 
13.4 
12.9 

61-56 

20,664 
14,106 
7,977 
2,333 

66-60  

7.2 

28-30 

61-66 

4.1 

Over  65 

1.2 

Total 

196,667 

100.0 

46-60     .            

Data  are  as  of  May  1, 1938  and  cover  employees  carrying  group  life  insurance;  on  date  indicated,  insured 
employees  represented  about  97%  of  ^;he  total  of  all  employees. 


EMPLOYEES  BY  AGE  GROUPS 

U.S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
MAY  1,  1938 


I 


mom 


5     !5     S     S     S     S     S 


•S  cScMMrr}?*!??*}? 


YEARS  OF  AGE 


HALF  OF  EMPLOYEES  ARE  OVER  40  YEARS  OF  AGE 


About  half  the  employees  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  are  over  40  years 
of  ago.  There  are  more  employees  between  the  ages  of  41  and  45  than  in 
any  other  group. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13875 

Skilled,  semi-skilled  and  common  labor  employees — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and 
subsidiaries — year  1938 


Class  of  Employees 

Number  of 
Employees 

Per  Cent 
of  Total 

Skilled  and  Semi-Skllled 

179, 672 
22,436 

88  0 

Common  Labor      . .... 

11  1 

Total 

202,108 

100  0 

Number  of  employees  represents  the  average  number  on  rolls  during  the  year. 

Administrative  and  sales  employees,  representing  6%  of  the  total  in  1938,  are  included  with  skilled  and 
semi-skilled  employees. 


SKILLED,  SEMI-SKILLED  AND  COMIVION  LABOR  EMPLOYEES 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
YEAR  1938 


COMMON  LABOR 

EMPLOYEES 

11?5 


SKILLED  AND 

SEMISKILLED 

EMPLOYEES 

89« 


The  steel  industry  Is  one  that  requires  skilled  labor.  In  1938  about  ^'i% 
of  all  employees  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries  were  stilled 
or  semi-sltilled. 


13876  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Payroll  and  component  factors — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries 


Payroll 

(000 

Omitted) 


Number 
of  Em- 
ployees 


Earnings 
Hour 


Hours 


Index  Nos.  W29=100 


Pay-      No.  of 
roU      Em  pi's 


E.  per    H.  per 
Hour      Week 


1920 
1930 
1931 
1932 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun.. 
Jul- 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Doc. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun.. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun.. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 

May 
Jun.. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


253, 138 
251, 782 
215,  649 
164,319 

(Above  represent  average 
monthly  payroll) 


$35,006 
32,606 
22,239 
11,159 


$0,686 
0.6S7 
0.691 
0.614 


46.2 
43.3 
34.3 
25.4 


$9,070 

151,010 

$0,569 

23.8 

26 

60 

83 

8,705 

147, 369 

0.677 

25.6 

26 

68 

84 

8,557 

139,585 

0.573 

24.2 

24 

55 

84 

8,895 

143,922 

0.561 

25.7 

25 

57 

82 

10,807 

150, 651 

0.543 

29.8 

31 

60 

79 

13,  769 

170,767 

0.533 

sa.3 

39 

67 

■78 

17,663 

190, 170 

0.663 

37.4 

50 

75 

82 

19, 591 

200,749 

0.596 

37.0 

66 

79 

87 

17:238 

200,633 

0.827 

32.0 

49 

79 

91 

17,095 

189  696 

0.646 

31.5 

49 

75 

94 

15,561 

192,438 

0.659 

2S.  6 

44 

76 

96 

16,198 

189,229 

0.658 

29.4 

46 

76 

96 

$15,322 

185,433 

$0,660 

28.3 

44 

73 

96 

16,497 

186,  686 

0.666 

31.2 

44 

74 

97 

18,231 

190, 153 

0.666 

33.0 

52 

75 

95 

19,  705 

194,669 

0.720 

32.8 

56 

77 

105 

22,648 

204,033 

0.710 

35.3 

65 

81 

103 

22,  741 

207,  731 

0.706 

36.1 

66 

82 

103 

17,627 

203,416 

0.717 

27.2 

50 

80 

106 

17,282 

192,038 

0.723 

28.1 

49 

76 

105 

14.  972 

186,693 

0.730 

25.8 

43 

73 

106 

16,  779 

178,426 

0.723 

27.6 

45 

70 

105 

15,  226 

175,  737 

0.730 

27.6 

43 

69 

106 

15,  572 

174,  350 

0.731 

27.6 

44 

69 

107 

$19,  080 

181,  825 

$0.  725 

32.7 

65 

72 

106 

19,733 

191,026 

0.734 

36.2 

56 

76 

107 

21,411 

194, 992 

0.727 

34.1 

61 

77 

106 

20,752 

196, 260 

0.730 

33.8 

59 

78 

106 

21  2.S8 

197,284 

0.727 

33.5 

61 

78 

106 

19,930 

197.269 

0.733 

32.1 

67 

78 

107 

20,212 

195,940 

0.  725 

32.2 

58 

77 

106 

21,  427 

196,534 

0.725 

33.9 

61 

78 

106 

20,589 

196,  524 

0.730 

33.5 

59 

78 

106 

22,  684 

195,  585 

0.733 

35.7 

65 

77 

107 

22,  014 

197,  984 

0.742 

34.9 

63 

78 

108 

22,455 

195, 975 

0.739 

35.1 

64 

77 

108 

$22,  896 

195,  858 

$0.  733 

36.0 

65 

77 

107 

22,  201 

197,463 

0.733 

38.3 

63 

78 

107 

24, 167 

200,  709 

0.728 

37.3 

69 

79 

106 

26,662 

211,008 

0.730 

40.5 

76 

83 

106 

28,009 

219,664 

0.724 

39.8 

80 

87 

106 

28,912 

222,  979 

0.737 

41.0 

83 

88 

107 

29,  567 

229, 452 

0.742 

39.3 

84 

91 

108 

30,128 

234,  972 

0.739 

39.2 

86 

93 

108 

30, 097 

237,  570 

0.725 

40.8 

86 

94 

106 

31,  774 

238,944 

0.719 

41.7 

91 

94 

105 

31,119 

240,  014 

0.750 

40.3 

89 

95 

106 

33,336 

238.  781 

0.778 

40.6 

96 

94 

113 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13877 

Payroll  and  component  factors — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries — Contd. 


Pajrroll 

(000 

Omitted) 

Number 
of  Em- 
ployees 

Earnings 
Hour 

Hours 

wiek 

Index  Nos 

.  1929  =  100 

'„T 

No.  of 
Em  pi's 

E.per 
Hour 

H.  per 
Week 

1937 

Jan 

$33,177 
32,293 
39,065 
40,857 
41,906 
42,517 
42,383 
42,394 
39,625 
34,484 
28,749 
26,477 

240,359 
244,602 
254,911 
260,565 
267,052 
272, 655 
276, 897 
278, 178 
276,202 
270,  515 
256,788 
236,665 

$0,780 
0.785 
0.831 

0.895 
0.894 
0.901 
0.894 
0.877 
0.863 
0.866 
0.877 

39.9 
42.0 
41.8 
40.9 
39.6 
40.6 
38.6 
38.5 

3313 
30.3 
27.9 

95 
92 
112 
117 
120 
121 
121 
121 
113 
99 
82 
73 

95 
97 
100 
103 
105 
108 
109 
110 
109 
107 
101 
93 

114 
114 
121 
131 
130 
130 
131 
130 

126 
126 
128 

Feb .  .. 

Mar 

90 

Apr 

89 

Xy " 

86 

Jun 

88 

Jul 

83 

Sep".: : : 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec — 

1938 

Jan 

$23,560 
20,923 
23,842 
22,655 
22,321 
21,961 
21, 194 
22,897 
23,146 
25,358 
27,186 
27,177 

220,270 
210, 580 
204,819 
203,816 
201,623 
196,  898 
192,021 
191,311 
192, 321 
197,271 
206,709 
207,370 

$0,887 
0.896 
0.892 
0.908 
0.910 
0.919 
0.931 
0.906 
0.901 
0.890 
0.892 

27.2 
27.7 
29.4 
28.6 
27.5 
28.3 
26.8 
29.8 
31.2 

34  5 
33.3 

67 
60 
68 
65 
64 
63 
61 
65 
66 
73 
78 
78 

87 
83, 
81 
81 
80 
78 
76 
76 
76 
78 
•81 
82 

129 
131 
130 
132 
133 
134 
136 
132 
131 
130 
130 
130 

69 

Feb 

60 

Mar 

Apr 

Uny 

62 
60 

Jun 

Jul 

68 

Aug 

65 

Sep.'   ::.: :" 

68 

Oct. 

Nov 

Dec 

72 

1939 

Jan 

$27,223 
26,344 
29,499 
26,404 
26,684 
28,308 
27.884 
30,980 

206,716 
208,995 
211,011 
195, 764 
212,381 
213,728 
214,205 
214,108 

$0,894 
0.899 
0.895 
0.902 
0.890 
0.899 
0.912 
0.896 

33.2 
35.1 
35.3 
33.5 
31.9 
34.4 
32.3 
36.4 

78 
75 
84 
73 
76 
81 
80 
88 

82 
83 
83 
77 
84 
84 
85 
85 

130 
131 
130 
131 
130 
131 
133 
131 

72 

Feb 

76 

Mar 

76 

Apr 

73 

May--  "-:-:-:■'- 

Jun -    . 

Jul 

Aug 

79 

Payroll  figures  include  construction  payroll. 

Number  of  employees  represents  number  on  rolls  duiing  month. 


13878 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


PAYROLL  AND  COMPONENT  FACTORS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
1929  =  100 


PAYROL 

f\ 

"* 

~N 

/ 

'    \ 

kJ 

\ 

A 

/Aj/" 

/ 

\ 

tJ'" 

\ 

V 

h 

V. 

J 

1929  1930  1931  1932  1933  1934  1935  1936  1937  1938  1939  1940 


EARNINGS  .^ 
PER  HOURr^- 

-^ 

-«A 

K^ 

,             . 

y    ^  NUMBER  OF 
y\.  run  i-ivrcc 

■^ 

>N^ 

-^ 

/^ 

^ 

^M- 

^ 

S^ 

vA 

A 

fT 

^     HC 
PER 

URS  \ 

week\ 

7 

AA 

^-11 

>f 

v 

1929  1930  1931  1932  1933  1934  1935  1936  1937  1938  1939  1940 


.  D*T»  192»I932.  MOHTHIT  DAT*  WOXKXUi 


Total  payroll  is  affected  by  throe  factors,  (a)  number  of  employees,  (b) 
number  of  hours  worked,  and  (c)  hourly  wage  rates. 
Since  1929.  hourly  earnings  of  employees  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporotion 
have  been  well  maintained  and  since  1936  have  been  approximately  30% 
above  the  1929  level.  Decreases  in  total  payroll  in  the  depression  periods 
have  largely  been  due  to  reductions  in  number  of  employees  and  hours 
worked  per  week,  made  necessary  by  the  absence  of  orders  for  steel 
products. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13879 

Wages  and  hours — U.  S.  Steel  manufacturing  subsidiaries 


Ave 

Year  or  Month      ^^|? 

Ho 

rage 
tags 
sr 
ur 

Average 

Hours 

Per 

Week 

Average 

Earntags 

Per 

Week 

Year  or  Month 

Average 

Earnings 

Per 

Hour 

Average 
Hours 

W^le'k 

Average 

Earntags 

Per 

Week 

1929                                  $0 

641 
634 
615 
618 
625 
632 
660 
676 
825 
843 
580 
586 
586 
650 
661 
646 
639 
648 
647 
660 
661 
663 
663 
661 
669 
662 
660 
656 
660 
659 
660 
664 
667 
664 
663 
658 
669 
665 
661 
680 
687 

47.5 
43.2 
31.3 
22.0 
29.4 
28.6 
33.4 
40.2 
37.4 
27.5 
26.3 
29.7 
32.1 
32.4 
35.6 
35.9 
24.6 
25.3 
23.1 
25.2 
27.3 
28.2 
32.1 
34.3 
33.5 
33.5 
32.8 
30.5 
31.2 
33.6 
33.2 
35.6 
36.1 
35.2 
36.5 

37!  9 
41.4 
40.6 
41.6 
39.4 

$30.47 
27.38 
19.28 
11.42 
15.43 
18.09 
22.02 
27.20 
30.84 
23.16 
15.27 
17.39 
18.79 
21.03 
23.14 
23.18 
15.63 
16.37 
14.94 
16.39 
17.77 
17.10 
20.97 
22.66 
22.06 
22.19 
21.65 
20.01 
20.25 
22.12 
21.95 
23.66 
23.41 
23.37 
24.17 
25.25 
24.99 
27.53 
26.77 
28.20 
27.07 

Aug 

$0,683 
.664 
.660 
.691 
.726 
.726 
.730 
.794 
.865 
.872 
.872 
.881 
.871 
.840 
.814 
.805 
.806 
.808 
.820 
.834 
.853 
.856 
.868 
.877 
.863 

:iro 

.839 
.832 
.832 
.836 
.841 
.846 
.848 

:iJ 

.862 

39.6 
41.2 
42.6 
41.2 
41.6 
41.4 
43.1 
43.0 
42.1 
40.0 
40.8 
38.0 
38.1 
37.4 
31.7 
28.1 
25.0 
24.1 
24.7 
27.0 
26.1 
24.9 
26.4 
23.8 
27.4 
29.2 
31.3 
33.7 
32.2 
31.9 
33.3 
33.9 
31.6 
31.7 
32.1 
30.0 
35.4 

$27.04 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

30.07 

Jan. 'W 

30.06 

Feb 

31.46 

1936 

Mar 

34.11 

1937 

Apr 

36.43 

1938 

May....... 

34.88 

Jan  '34 

Jun" 

35  66 

Feb 

Jul 

33  61 

Mar 

Aug 

33.19 

Anr 

Sep 

31  38 

^y 

0(*" ""■ 

25  80 

jSn^::::::::::::::: 

Nov 

22.61 

Jul 

Dec. 

20.13 

Jan.  '38 

19.44 

Sep;.:::::::::::::: 

Feb 

20.21 

o5 

Mar 

22.63 

Nov 

Apr 

22.27 

Dec 

^ay ' '"■ 

21.31 

Jan.  '35 

Jun 

22.03 

Feb 

Jul 

20.89 

M„ 

Aug 

23.37 

Apr 

Sep 

24.66 

^y    : 

Oct : 

26.26 

jSn 

Nov     

m:3o 

jSi 

Dec                

26.82 

Aug 

Jan.  '39 

26.54 

Feb             .      .. 

27.84 

qK 

Mar 

28.64 

Nov 

26.62 

Dec 

May 

28.90 

Jan.  '36 

Jun           ..    ..  . 

27.83 

Frt.       

Jul    :   :::: 

26.42 

Ma 

Aug   ..           .: 

30.49 

Apr 

Sep    .       .    .. 

wii :  : 

Oct         :: :: 

-Tnn 

Nov         .    .      . . 

Jul.- 

Dec               

Data  are  for  wage  earners  only,  exclusive  of  all  salaried  employees. 
Figures  prior  to  1933  are  partially  estimated,  based  on  samples. 


13880 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


WAGES  AND  HOURS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  MANUFACTURING  SUBSIDIARIES 
AVERAGE  EARNINGS  PER  HOUR 

1.00 

«     so 

i: 

.20 
0 

60 
50 

«       40 
a: 

g        30 

^        20 

10 

0 

40 
30 

3        20 

o 

10 

0 

ANNUAL  DATA  19M 

1.00 

so      « 
.60       5 
.40       g 
20 
0 

60 
50 
40        „ 

30    i 

20        ^ 

10 

0 

40 

30 

20        1 

10 

r\ 

y^ 

^^ 

_^ 

_^ 

J  ^ 

^ 

1929   '30     31     '32    '33     '34    '35     'SS     '37     '38    '39    1940 

AVERAGE  HOURS  PER  WEEK 

^ 

^  A 

'\, 

\ 

A 

hi/* 

^ 

^ 

^ 

'I 

J 

1929  -30     '31     '32     '33     '34     '35    '36     '37     '38    '39    1940 

AVERAGE  EARNINGS  PER  WEEK 

A 

N 

s. 

A 

0'' 

/^ 

\ 

J 

jj 

\ 

V 

^ 

/I 

f 

1929   '30    '31     '32     '33     '34    "35    '36     '37     '38    '39    1940 
•1933.  MONTHLY  DATA  THEREAHER 

Average  earnings  per  hour  of  wage  earners  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  manufacturing  subsidiaries  are 
about  30%  higher  today  than  in  1 929. 

Due  to  the  Corporation's  policy  of  sharing  the  available  work  so  far  as  practicable  among  the  maximum 
number  of  employees  during  depression  periods,  average  hours  per  week  reached  a  level  in  1938  almost 
as  low  as  that  of  19^2.  With  the  improving  demand  for  steel  whi..,i  began  in  the  Fall  of  1938,  more  work 
became  available  and  by  August  1939,  average  hours  per  week  had  increased  to  about  35'/2- 
Average  earnings  per  week  at  the  low  point  of  1938  were  substantially  above  the  low  point  of  1932,  on 
account  of  the  higher  hourly  rate.  In  August  1939,  despite  a  twelve  hour  shorter  work  week,  weekly 
earnings  were  slightly  higher  than  in  1929. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13881 


(Vages  and  hours — U.   S.   Steel  Corporation  manufacturing  subsidiaries  and  all 
manufacturing  industries 


Year  or  Month 


1929. 
1930. 
1931. 
1932. 
1933. 
1934. 
1935. 
1936. 


1938 

Jan.,  '34. 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May..... 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug 

Sep 

Oct 

Nor 

Dec 

Jan.,  '35. 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May..  . 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug 

Sep 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

Jan.,  '36. 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May-. 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug 

Sep 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

Jan., '37. 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr - 

May 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug 

Sep 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

Jan.,  '38. . 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug 

Sep 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

Jan.,  '39. . 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May..... 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug 


Average  Earnings  per 
Hour 


U.  S.  Steel     All  Mfrg, 


$0,641 


61.-) 

518 

625 

$0,460 

632 

.548 

660 

.568 

676 

.676 

m 

.643 

843 

.646 

680 

.533 

685 

.631 

586 

.631 

650 

.541 

651 

.561 

645 

.550 

639 

.556 

648 

.555 

647 

.559 

av) 

.553 

651 

.564 

6,53 

.560 

653 

.564 

47.5 
43.2 
31.3 
22.0 
29.4 

33^4 
40.2 
37.4 
27.5 

29!  7 

32.1 

32.4 

36.6 

35.9 

24.5 

25.3 

23.1 

25.2 

27.3 

26.2 

32.1 

34.3 

33.5 

33.5 

32.8 

30.5 

31.2 

33.6 

33.2 

35.6 

36.1 

35.2 

36.5 

38.4 

37. 

41. 

40.6 

41.5 


41.2 

42.6 

41.2 

41.5 

41.4 

43.1 

43.0 

42. 

40.0 

40. 

38.0 

38.1 

37.4 

31.7 

25^0 
24  1 
24.7 
27.0 
26.1 
24.9 
25.4 
23.8 
27.4 
29.2 
31.3 
33.7 
32.2 
31.9 
33.3 
33.9 
31.5 
31.7 
32.1 


All  Mfrg. 


37.9 
34.7 
36.6 

38!  5 
35.3 

3518 
36.3 
36.2 
35.4 
34.9 
33.4 
34.0 

34^3 
34.1 
35.2 
35.2 
36.4 
36.6 
36.4 
35.8 
35.4 
35.2 
36.6 
37.4 
38.2 
37.8 
38.7 
37.3 
37.4 
38.6 
38.7 
39.2 
39.2 
38.5 
39.4 
38.7 
40.5 
40.6 
41.1 

40.4 
41.0 
40.4 
39.8 
39.2 
37.9 

37^4 
37.6 
35.4 
34.4 
33.2 
34.3 
34.5 
34.2 
34.4 
34.4 
34.7 
36.3 
36.9 
37.4 
36.5 
37.1 

36!  9 
37.1 
36.4 
36.7 
37.2 


$30.47 
27.38 
19.28 
11.42 
15.43 
18.09 
22.02 
27.20 
30.84 
23.15 
15.27 
17.39 
18.79 
21.03 
23.14 
23.18 
16.63 
16.37 
14.94 
16.39 
17.77 
17.10 
20.97 
22.66 
22.06 
22.19 
21.65 
20.01 
20.25 
22.12 
21.95 
23.66 
23.41 
23.37 
24.17 
25.25 
24.99 
27.53 
26.77 
28.20 
27.07 
27.04 
27.35 


30.07 
30.06 
31.45 
34.11 
36.43 
34.88 
35.  55 
33.51 
33. 19 
31.38 
25.80 
22.61 
20.13 
19.44 
20.21 
22.  .53 
22.27 
21.31 
22.03 
20.89 
23.37 
24.65 
26.26 
28.30 
26.82 
26.54 
27.84 
28.54 
26.62 
26.90 
27.83 
26.42 
30.4'J 


13882 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Wages  and  hours — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  manufacturing  subsidiaries  and  all 
manufacturing  industries — Continued 


Year  or  Month 

Average  Earnings  per " 
Hour 

AveraM  Hours  per 

Average  Earnings  per 
Week 

U.  S.  steel 

All  Mfrg. 

U.  8.  Steel 

All  Mfrg. 

U.  8.  Steel 

All  Mfrg. 

Oct 

Nov    

Deo 

Source:  Corporation  recordsland  U.  S.  Bmeau  of  Labor]Statistlcs. 

U.  8.  Steel  data  are  for  wage  earners  only,  exclusive  of  salaried  employees;  data  prior  to  1933  are  partially 
estimated,  based  on  samples. 

Data  for  all  manufacturing  industries  are  those  of  U.  8.  B.  L.  8.  and  cover  wage  earners  In  89  manufactur- 
ing Industries;  data  are  not  available  prior  to  1932. 


WAGES  AND  HOURS 


U.  S.  STEEL  M'FR'G  SUBSIDIARIES  AND  ALL  MTR'G  INDUSTRIES 
AVERAGE  EARNINGS  PER  HOUR 


1 

I.  S.  STEEL /^ 

^^ 

=:=_ 

— 

^ 

-^MANUFACTURING 

1 

-7 

•32     '33     '3*     -35    '36    '37     "38     39    1940 


60p 

A 

VER/ 

^GE 

HOU 

RS 

>ER  WEE 

K 

r-i 

^^ 

ALL 

\, 

^\ 

f^ 

^x 

^ 

Zj 

30 

\y 

y^ 

'\f 

U.  S.'  STEEL 

^• 

. 

1929  -30     '31     -32    '33    '34     '35    '36    '37     '38    '39    1940 

AVERAGE  EARNINGS  PER  WEEK 


... 

Ja 

N 

V 

A 

MAr 

UFAC 

h 

^ 

fJ 

s 

-^ 

/b 

TURI 

IG 

.... 

20     :; 


1929  '30     '31     '32     '33     '34     '35    '36    '37     '38     '39    1940 

ANNUAl  AND  MONTHLV  DATA  SHOWN  Soufrt.  CofiaMoo  itmik  and  USB  LS. 


Average  earnings  per  hour  of  wage  earners  in  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  manufacturing  subsidiaries  a'e 
considerably  higher  than  earnings  per  hour  in  manufacturing  industries  generally. 

Average  hours  per  week  in  Corporation  subsidiaries  tend  to  fluctuate  with  hours  per  week  'n  ail  manu- 
facturing industries  but  in  greater  degree.  In  periods  of  low  operation,  weekly  hours  in  Corporation, 
subsidiaries  are  below  those  in  all  manufatturlng  industries,  and  In  periods  of  high  operation  they  are 
above. 

Average  earnings  per  week  in  Corporation  subsidiaries  tend  to  be  above  those  in  all  manufacturing 
industries  even  though  hours  per  week  in  the  former  are  the  lower,  as  in  1939.  This  is  because  of  the 
higher  hourly  rate  In  Corporation  subsidiaries  which,  in  1939,  was  more  than  20  cents  an  hour  above  that 
In  manufacturing  industries  generally. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13883 

Average  weekly  earnings  compared  with  cost  of  living — wage  earners  of  U.  S.  Steel 
Corporation  subsidiaries 


Cost  of  Living 

Casli  Earnings 

Real  Earn. 

Year 

1923-25 
=100 

1929=100 

Dollars  per 
Week 

1929=100 

ings 
1929-100 

1929 

99.3 
97.2 
88.9 
80.3 
75.7 
78.3 
80.6 
81.9 
84.0 
83.6 

100.  D 
97.9 
89.5 
80.9 
7«.2 
78.9 
81.1 
82.5 
84.6 
84.1 

30.32 
27.19 
19.44 
11.48 
15.00 
17.93 
21.63 
26.79 
29.93 
23.06 

100.0 
89.7 
64.1 
37.9 
49.5 
59.1 
71.3 
88.4 
98.7 
76.1 

100.0 

1930 

91.6 

1931 

71.6 

1932 

46.8 

1933 

65.0 

1934 

74.9 

1936 

87.9 

1936 

107.2 

1937 

116.7 

1938 

90.5 

Source:  Corporation  records  and  U.  8.  B'lreau  of  Labor  Statistics. 

Yearly  cost  of  living  data  computed  from  U.  8.  B.  L.  S.  first,  middle  and  Iflit  Of  year  data  by  weiigblng  flrgt 
and  last  of  year  figures  by  one  and  the  middle  of  the  yeer  figure  by.two. 
Real  earnings  equal  cash  earnings  dlTided  by  cost  if  living. 


AVERAGE  WEEKLY  EARNINGS  COMPARED  WITH  COST  OF  LIVING 

WAGE  EARNERS  OF  U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  SUBSIDIARIES 

1929=100 

120 

120 
100 
80 
60 
40 
20 
0 

RE 

ALEAfiN 

NGS^ 

Ul 

i      80 

a 

2      40 

20 

0 
I 

b 

1ST  OF  U 

VING 

y 

^ 

/ 

-5^ 

y 

V 

UJ 

i 

3 
Z 

'x 

o 

2 

^ 

s. 

r- 

\ 

<i 

^<. 

KEARNII 

SS 

"- 

1930 
1931 
1932 
1933 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 
1938 
1939 

MOTC:  KM.  EAKNINeSEQWl  CASH  EARNINGS  WVIOEB  BY  COST  Of  UVINO 
Sout..- Cop<»l«n«a«4«/USffXS 

In  1938,  average  weekly  earnings  of  all  wage  earners  of  U.  S.  Steel 
Corporation  subsidiaries  were  more  than  20%  below  those  in  1929. 
However,  since  the  cost  of  living  in  1938  was  also  below  that  in  1929. 
real  weekly  earnings  (i.  e.,  cash  earnings  divided  by  cost, of  living)  of 
Corporation  wage  earners  were  only  10%  below  the  1929  level. 

With  improved  business  conditions  in  1939.  weekly  earnings  of  Corpora- 
tion wage  earners  had  recovered  by  August  to  approximately  the  1929 
level.  At  that  time,  the  cost  of  living  was  still  about  1 5%  below  the  1929 
average,  so  that  real  eamings  of  Corporation  wage  earners  were  nearly 
20%  above  the  1 929  point. 


-124491— 41— pt.  26- 


13884 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEP 


V/age  rates  and  steel  prices 


(Wage  rates=U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  Mfrg.  subidlaries'  basic  rate  per  hour  for  common  labor  (Pitts- 
burgh district);  steel  prices=Iron  Age  composite  price  of  finished  steel] 

STEEL  PRICES  (IRON  AOE) 


Year 

Price  Per 
Net  Ton 

1914  =  100 

Year 

Price  Per 
Net  Ton 

1914 > 100 

$44.14 
40.80 
41.14 
37.36 
34.14 
35.20 
35.40 
38.  M 
37.30 
32.64 
33.52 
30.84 
30.54 
33.22 
28.66 
30.66 
53.34 
83.82 
70.84 
62.30 

154. 01 
142.36 
143. 55 
130.36 

119. 12 
122.82 
123.  52 
134. 19 

130. 13 
113.89 
116.96 
107.61 
a06.56 
115.91 
100.00 
106.97 
186.11 
292.46 
247.17 
217.38 

1920 

$74.74 
48.74 
42.48 
53.94 
50.10 
46.68 
46.30 
44.04 
43.30 
44.18 
40.96 
39.14 
38.02 
37.68 
40.66 
41.16 
41.54 
49.28 
47.88 
46.20 

260.78 

1901 

1921 - 

170.06 

1902 

1922 ..- 

148.22 

1903        

1923 

188.21 

1904 

1924 

1925 

174.81 

1906     

162.88 

1906 - ---- 

1926 .- - 

161. 66 

1907 

1927 

153  66 

1906 

1928 

151  08 

1909 

1929.... 

1930 

154.16 

1910 

142  92 

1911 

1931 

136  57 

1912 

1932 

1933 

1934 

132. 66 

1913 

131  12 

1914 

141.87 

1915 

1936 

143. 61 

1916 

1936 

144  94 

1917 

1937 

171. 95 

1918 

1938 

167.06 

1919 

1939  > 

157.  71 

'  steel  price  data  for  1939  are  basis  of  first  9  months. 

WAGE  RATES  (U.  S.  S.  C.  Subs.) 


DateEflective  ^HoiJ*'^       1914-100 


Jan.  1,1901.. 
Jun.  1,1902.. 
Jan.  1, 1904.. 
Apr.  1, 1905.. 
Jan.  1,1907.. 
May  1, 1910.. 
Feb.  1,  1913.. 
Feb.  1,  1916.. 
May  1,  1916.. 
Dec.  16,  1916. 
May  1,  1917.. 
Oct.  1,  1917.. 
Apr.  16,  1918. 
Aug.  1,  1918.. 
Oct.  1,  1918- . 


75.0 
80.0 
72.5 
77.5 
82.6 
87.6 
100.0 
110.0 
126.0 
137.  S 
150.0 
165.0 
190.0 
210.0 
234.1 


Date  Effective 


Feb.  1,  1920.. 
May  16,  1921. 
Jul.  16,  1921.. 
Aug.  29,  1921. 
Sep.  1,  1922.  - 
Apr.  16,  1923. 
Aug.  16,  1923. 
Oct.  1,1931-- 
May  16, 1932. 
Jul.  16,  1933.- 
Sep.  16,  1933. 
Apr.  1,  1934-- 
Nov.  16,  1936 
Mar.  16,  19.37 


Rate  Per 
Hoi^ 


$0. 5128 
.4125 
.37 
:30 


256.4 
206.2 
185.0 
150.0 
180.0 
200.0 
220.0 
195.0 
166.0 
200.0 
212.5 
235.0 
262.6 
312.5 


From  August  16, 1923  to  September  16, 1933,  common  labor  is  that  of  10  hour  men;  subsequent  to  Septem- 
ber 16,  1933,  rat"  is  that  of  8  hour,  non-continuous  labor. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13885 


WAGE  RATES  AND  STEEL  PRICES 

1914  =  100 

300 

^     250 
er 

i     200 

Z 

300 

. 

f 

I 

250     ^ 

X 
LU 
00 

200     S 

Z 

150     X 

UJ 

100    ^      . 

50 

0 

y 

i4 

re 

WAG 

tRATi 

i-i 

;! 

.-- 

i 

TE 

EL 

PI 

m 

E£ 

• 

f 

> 

1 

1 

-.^ 

UJ 

O 

^     100- 
50  - 

^> 

S  ^ 

- 

> 

^ 

^ 

" 

j 

I 

»v 

-' 

-' 

■■- 

r- 

- 

•■ 

r 

' 

.  U  S  S<~/  G.pc«,«y,  ™.,y««^  »iW..«,,  Rmto,9*  <t*rt,  !«<  ,«  p«  /«., 

^  1  s  II 

.feroynmonbtor 

1 

Wage  rates  today,  as  represented  by  the  common  labor  rate  per  houc 
of  manufacturing  subsidiaries  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  in  the  Pittsburgh 
District,  are  more  than  ff  ur  times  as  high  as  at  the  beginning  of  the  cen- 
tury. Current  steel  pric  js,  as  represented  by  the  Iron  Age  composite 
price  of  finished  steel,  jre  practically  at  the  same  level  as  in  1900,  with- 
out attempting  any  adjustment  for  the  great  improvement  in  quality 
which  has  occurred  during  the  inter/al. 


13886 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Average  earnings  per  hour  and  common  labor  rate- — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 
manufacturing  subsidiaries 


AVERAGE  EARNINGS  PER  HOUR-ALL  WAGE  EARNERS 


1929 

1930 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934: 

Jan 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr -_. 

May --. 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug 

Sep 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

1935: 

Jan 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug 

Sep 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

1936: 

Jan - 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May 

Jun 

Jul 

Aug 

DaU  prior  to  1933  partially  estimated, 


$0.  641 
.634 
.615 
.518 
.526 

.580 
.585 
.586 
.650 
.651 
.645 
.639 
.648 
-.647 
.650 
.651 
.653 

.653 
.661 
.659 
.662 
.660 
.656 
.650 
.659 
.660 
.664 
.667 


.658 
.659 
.665 
.661 
.680 
.687 
.683 


1936: 


1937: 


Sep.. 
Oct.. 
Nov- 
Dec- 


$0. 


Jan.- 
Feb.. 
Mar. 
Apr.. 
May. 
Jun.. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 


Oct.- 

Nov. 

Dec. 
1938: 

Jan.. 

Feb.. 

Mar. 

Apr.. 

May. 

Jun._ 

JuL- 

Aug- 

Sep-- 

Oct.. 

Nov. 

Dec-. 
1939: 

Jan.- 

Feb.. 

Mar. 

Apr.. 

May. 

Jun.. 

Jul._ 

Aug. 


664 
660 
691 
725 

726 
730 
794 
865 
872 
872 
881 
871 
840 
814 
805 
805 


820 
834 
853 
856 
868 
877 
853 
844 
840 


832 
836 
841 
846 

848 


862 


based  on  samples. 


COMMON  LABOR  RATE-COMMON  LABOR  EMPLOYEES  IN  PITTSBURGH  DISTRICT 


Date  Effective: 
Jan.  1,  1901.- 
Jun.  1,  1902- - 
Jan.  1,  1904- - 
Apr.  1,  1905- - 
Jan.  1,  1907.. 
May  1,  1910-- 
Feb.  1,  1913.- 
Feb.  1,  1916- . 
May  1,  1916-. 
Dec.  16,  1916. 
May  1,  1917-. 
Oct.  1,  1917.. 
Apr.  16,  1918. 
Aug.  1,  1918-. 
Oct.  1,  1918.. 


From  August 
September  16,  Ifl 


Rale  per  Hour 

..  $0.  15 

--  .  16 

--  .  145 

..  .155 

..  .165 

..  .175 

-.  .20 

--  .22 

.-  .25 

..  .275 

-.  .30 

..  .33 

--  .38 

..  .42 

--  .4683 


Date  Effective— Con.             R<^'  ver  Hour 
Feb.  1,  1920 $0.  5128 


May  16,  1921. 
Jul.  16,  1921-. 
Aug.  29,  1921. 
^p.  1,  1922.. 
Apr.  16,  1923. 
Aug.  16,  1923- 
Oct.  1,  1931 -. 
May  16,  1932. 
Jul.  16,  1933- 
Sep.  16,  1933. 
Apr.  1,  1934.. 
Nov.  16,  1936. 
Mar.  16,  1937. 


4125 
37 


40 

425 

47 

525 

625 


6,  1923,  to  September  16,  1933,  common  labor  rate  i 
3,  rate  is  that  of  8-hour,  non-continuous  labor. 


that  of  10-hour  men;  subsequent  to 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13887 


AVERAGE  EARNINGS  PER  HOUR  AND  COMMON  LABOR  RATE 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  MANUFACTURING  SUBSIDIARIES 


1 

A 

A- 

^ 

1 

1 

} 

— 

— 

— V 

EARNINGS  __^ 
PER  HOURp^ 

^ 

r~" 

_^_ 



> 

\__ 

_^ 

r 

i 

— 

— 

' 'l 

J" 

J- 

COMMO^ 
BOR  RA 

1 J 

"L. 

J 

1929    1930    1931    1932    1933    1934    1935    1936    1937    1938    1939    1940 


The  common  labor  rate  at  Pittsburgh  Is  a  goo?i  measure  of  the  trend  of 

earnings  per  hour  of  employees  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  manufacturing 

subsidiaries. 

Vacation  wages  paid  in  the  summers  of  1937,  1938  and  1939  caused  the 

Increases  in  earnings  per  hour  during  those  periods.  Vacation  wages  paid 

to  wage  earners  of  manufacturing  subsidiaries  in  1937  and  1938  amounted 

to  $3,744,346  and  $3,1  14,134,  respectively. 


13888 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Earnings  per  hour  and  steel  prices — Earnings  per  hour — Earnings  per  hour  of  all 
employees  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries;  steel  prices — Iron  Age 
composite  price  of  finished  steel 


Hourly  Earnings 


cents 
perHr. 


1926= 
100 


102.8 
103.0 
103,6 
92.1 


cents       1926= 
per  lb.        100 


2.209 
2.048 
1.957 
1.901 


Afi.9 

85.3 

1.885 

S7.7 

86.5 

1.873 

fi7.?. 

85.9 

1.867 

fifi.l 

84.1 

1.817 

64.8 

81.4 

1.802 

53.  3 

79.9 

1.820 

f)«.3 

84.4 

1.878 

59.6 

89  4 

62.7 

94.0 

1  890 

«4.6 

96.9 

1.950 

6S.9 

98.8 

1.933 

65.8 

98.7 

1.945 

109.9       2.062 
109. 9       2. 040 


95.4 
88.5 
84.5 
82.1 


81.4 
80.9 
80.6 
78.5 
77.8 
78.6 
81.1 
81.3 
81.6 
84.2 
83.5 
84.0 


66.0 

99.0 

1.946 

84 

66.5 

99.7 

1.946 

84 

«.■;,  5 

98.2 

1.94S 

84 

72.0 

107.9 

1.988 

85 

71.0 

106.4 

2.118 

91 

70.6 

105.8 

2.118 

91 

71.7 

107.5 

2.056 

88 

72.3 

108.4 

2.056 

8« 

73.0 

109.4 

2.056 

88 

72.  3 

108.4 

2.056 

KM 

73.  0 

109.4 

2.056 

73.1 

109.6 

2.056 

88 

72.5 

108.7 

2.056 

88 

n  4 

110.0 

2.056 

72,7 

109.0 

2.056 

88 

73,0 

109.4 

2.056 

88 

72.7 

109.0 

2.056 

88 

7;<.3 

109.9 

2.056 

88 

72.5 

108.7 

2.056 

8H 

72.5 

108.7 

2.066 

88 

73.0 

109.4 

2.056 

88 

n  3 

109.9 

2.062 

89 

74.2 

111.2 

2.062 

89 

73.0 

110.8 

2.062 

89 

Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul. 
Aug. 
Sep., 
Oct., 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct.. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan., 
Feb. 
Mar. 
Apr. 
May 
Jun. 
Jul.. 
Aug. 
Sep. 
Oct. 
Nov. 
Dec. 


Jan.. 
Feb.. 
Mar.. 
Apr.. 
May. 
Jun.. 
Jul... 
Aug.. 


Hourly  Earnings      Steel  Prices 


cents      1926= 
perHr.       100 


cents      1926- 
per lb.       100 


72.8 

109.1 

2.021 

73.0 

109.4 

2.028 

72.4 

108.6 

2.028 

73,7 

110,6 

2.033 

74.2 

111,2 

2.091 

73.9 

110,8 

2.091 

72.5 

108.7 

2.096 

71.9 

107.8 

2.116 

75  0 

112.4 

2.116 

77.8 

116,6 

2.199 

88.7 

133.0 

2.512 

89.6 

134.3 

2.512 

89.2 

133.7 

2.512 

90.8 

136.1 

2.512 

91.0 

136.4 

2.606 

91.9 

137.8 

2.459 

93.1 

139.6 

2,300 

90.6 

135.8 

2.300 

90.1 

135.1 

2.293 

89.0 

133.4 

2.255 

89.2 

133.7 

2.286 

88.9 

133.3 

2.286 

89,4 

134,0 

2.286 

89,9 

134.8 

2.286 

89.5 

134.2 

2.286 

90.2 

136.2 

2,286 

89.0 

133.4 

2.266 

89.9 

134.8 

2.236 

91  2 

136.7 

2.236 

89.6 

134.3 

2.236 

87.3 
87.6 
87.6 
87.8 
90.3 
90.3 
90.5 
91.4 
91.4 
95.0 


78.0 

116.9 

2.249 

78,5 

117.7 

2.249 

83,1 

124.6 

2.459 

1 

89,8 

134.6 

2.612 

1( 

89,5 

134.2 

2.512 

V 

89.4 

134.0 

2.512 

90.1 

136.1 

2.612 

\{ 

89,4 

134.0 

2.512 

V 

87.7 

131.6 

2.512 

V 

86.3 

129.4 

2:512 

V 

86.6 

129.8 

2.512 

I 

87.7 

131.5 

2.512 

u 

97.1 
97.1 
06.2 
08.5 
.08.6 
08.6 
6 
.08.6 
08.6 
08.6 
08.5 
08.5 


08.6 
08.6 
08.5 
08.6 
08.3 
06.2 
99.4 
99.4 
99.0 
97.4 
98.7 
98.7 


98.7 
98.7 
98.7 
98,7 
97.6 
96.6 
99.6 
96.6 


Steel  prices  are  monthly  averages  of  weekly  figures. 

The  1926  base  for  earnings  per  hour  of  all  employees  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries  was 
estimated  from  data  on  the  total  steel  industry  compiled  by  National  Industrial  Conference  Board,  as  Cor- 
poration data  are  not  available  prior  to  1929. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13889 


Earnings  per  hour  and  production — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  and  subsidiaries — 
April  19S7-November  1939 


1937 

1938 

1939 

Month 

Earnings 
Per  Hour 

Thousands 
or  Net  Tons 
Produced 

Earnings 
Per  Hour 

Thousands 
0/ Net  Tons 
Produced 

Earnings 
Per  Hour 

Thousands 
of  Net  Tons 
Produced 

Jan 

$0  887 

537 
467 
687 
532 
506 
522 
466 
623 
625 
734 
852 
777 

$0,894 
.899 
.895 
.902 
.890 
.899 
.912 
.896 
.893 
.890 
.893 

9S1 

Ft.:.: 

896 
892 
908 
910 
919 
931 
906 
901 
890 
892 

Mar. 

993 

1,483 
1,452 
1,438 
1,278 
1,247 
1,154 
869 
648 

S^y::::::::::::::::: :::::::: 

895 
894 
901 
894 
877 
863 

877 

Jul 

879 

Aug 

1  033 

Sep  — 

1  198 

Oct ::  :" " 

1  537 

Nov 

1,629 

Dec 

Average  relationship:  Earnings  per  hour=$0.901  minus  $0.0007  for  each  hundred  thousand  net  tons 
produced. 
Earnings  per  hour  are  average  hourly  earnings  of  all  employees. 
Production  data  represent  monthly  production  of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products. 


100 

90 

80 

§      70 

I      ^ 

§       50 

{2      40 

g       30 

20 

10 

0 

EARNINGS  PER  HOUR  AND  PRODUCTION 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
APRIL  1937  -  NOVEMBER  1939 

1            1 

AVERAGE 

. 

.^ 

100 

90 

80 

70      - 

60       S 

50      ^ 

40      g 

30      1 

20 

10 

0 

REL 

ATION 

SHIP 

♦ 

♦ 

*~ 

•  1939  MONTHS 
■  1938  MONTHS 

♦  1937  MONTHS 

-J 

c 

.1     .2     .3     .4     .5     .6     .7     .8     .9     1.0    1.1    12    1.3    1.4   1.5    1.6   1. 
MILLIONS    OF    NET    TONS 

i/e  A^tago  H>j'lf  £a,r,r,g,  cf  All  Empl^ms 

7 

While  average  hourly  earnings  of  all  employees  of  United  States  Steel 
Corporation  and  subsidiaries  vary  somewhat  from  month  to  month,  the 
voriations  are  small  and  bear  very  little  relation  to  the  rate  of  production. 
Averoge  hourly  earnings  tend  to  be  less  than  one  cent  per  hour  lower 
when  operations  ore  at  90%  of  capacity  than  when  operations  are  af  25% 
of  capacity. 


13890  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Ingot  production  and  number  of  employees,  total  steel  industry 


Item 

1929 

1937             1937  In 
(9  months)      %  of  1929 

Monthly  Ingot  Production  (Tons) 

4,  670, 869 
428,319 

4, 798, 000                   105 

NllPlN^r  of  nimplnypAa 

521  303                   122 

Ingot  production  represents  average  monthly  production  of  all  ingots,  and  excludes  production  of  castings. 

Number  of  employees  represents  number  of  wage  earners  of  iron  and  steel  manufacturing  companies 
reporting  to  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute  (1929  figure  partially  estimated,  based  on  data  of  U.  8. 
Census  of  Manufactures  on  wage  earners  in  Blast  Furnaces,  Steel  Works  and  Rolling  Mills). 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13891 


INGOT  PRODUCTION  AND  NUMBER  OF  EMPLOYEES 

TOTAL  STEEL  INDUSTRY 

1929  =  100 

INGOT                              NUMBER  ( 
PRODUCTION                          EMPLOYEE 

120 [ ■ 

n                            I 

)F 
S 

-120 

NUMBERS 

1                 1                1 

III 

-100 
-80. 
-60 

UJ 

m 

2 

z> 
z 

■SSi 

ggg 

X 

LU 

Q 

■z. 

-        40- 

20- 

1 

-40 
-20 

X 

UJ 

Q 

z 

1 

i 

0- 
] 

is 
92< 

3    1 

(9( 

93- 

/lONT 

7                                    1925 

HS) 

)   193: 

(9  MONT 

-0 

^S), 

TECHNOLOGICAL  ADVANCES  HAVE  NOT  RESULTED  IN 
FEWER  EMPLOYEES 

From  1929  to  1937,  a  period  morked  by  important  installations  of  continu- 
ous types  of  equipment  to  keep  pace  with  tecfinological  advances,  employ- 
ment increased  relatively  more  in  the  steel  industry  generally  thap  it  did 
in  the  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation.  Average  monthly  ingot  production  for  the 
industry  in  the  first  nine  months  of  1937  was  5%  more  than  in  1929,  whereas 
the  average  number  of  employees  in  the  first  nine  months  of  1937  was 
22%  more. 


13892 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


ill 


I 


til  tb  ^  ^ 


rr^ 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13893 

Exhibit  No.  1410 
SOME  FACTORS  IN  THE  PRICING  OF  STEEL 

This  is  an  analysis  made  in  connection  with  studies  by  the  United  States  Steel 
Corporation  in  preparation  for  hearings  on  the  steel  industry  before  the  Temporary 
National  Economic  Com  r.ittee. 

October  30,  1939. 

table  of  contents 

Introduction 

The  Demand  for  Steel 

Immediate  Source  of  Demand 
Geographic  Distribution 
Characteristics  of  Demand 
Derived  Nature  of  Demand 
Durability  and  Demand 
Postponability  of  Purchase  of  Durable  Goods 
Total  Demand  for  Steel  is  Inelastic 
Effect  of  the  Substitution  Factor 

Potential  Elasticity  of  Demand  from  a  Particular  Producer 
The  Supply  of  Steel 

Geographic  Concentration 
Technological  Aspects 
Capital  Investment  Requirements 
Factors  in  Expenditures  for  New  Plants  and  Equipment 
Source  of  Funds 

Incentives  for  Investment— Profit  Motive 
Incentives  for  Investment— Obsolescence 
Siie  and  Number  of  Producers 
Channels  of  Distribution 
Jobbers  and  Warehouses 
Importance  of  Outlets 
Summary 
Characteristics  of  Cost  in  the  Industry 
"Overhead"  or  "Fixed"  Costs 
•Additional"  Costs 
Average  Costs 
The  Dynamics  of  the  Market  for  Steel 
Costs  and  Demand 
Psychological  Factors 

Chiaraeterlstic  Patterns  of  Action  by  Sellers  in  the  Market  for  Steel 
The  Basing  Point  Method  of  Quoting  Delivered  Prices 

Economic  Roots  of  the  Basing  Point  Method 
Relation  of  Competition  to  Profits,  Capacity  and  Costs  of  Distribution 
Profits 
Capacity 

Distribution  Costs 
Selling  Expense 
Freight  Absorption 
Conclusion 

The  Function  of  the  Steel  Industry  in  the  National  Economy 
As  a  Source  of  Raw  Material 
As  a  Factor  in  Employment 
As  a  Factor  in  the  Growth  of  the  Nation 

Introduction 

How  much  does  the  price  of  steel  influence  the  quantity  sold?  What  is  the 
relationship  of  cost  to  the  price  of  steel?  What  degree  of  price  competition 
is  desirable,  and  possible,  in  the  steel  industry?  Why  does  the  steel  industry 
quote  delivered  prices  and  why  does  it  use  the  basing  point  method  of  quoting 
delivered  prices?  Does  the  steel  industry  perform  its  proper  function  in  the 
national  economy?  Before  these  questions  can  be  answered  a  careful  analjTsis 
must  be  made  of  the  fundamental  factors  underlying  the  demand-supply  situation 
in  the  industry. 

Subject  to  some  exceptions  with  respect  to  particular  products,  the  salient 
characteristics  of  demand  and  supply  in  the  steel  industry  may  be  summarized 
as  follows: 

(1)  The  demand  for  steel  is  marked  by  tremendous  cyclical  fluctuations. 

(2)  The  total  demand  for  steel  is  inelastic,  i.  e.,  the  total  quantity  of  steel 

bought  from  the  industry  would  not  be  greatly  different  at  any 
particular  time  if  the  price  were  higher  or  lower. 

(3)  In  contrast,  the  demand  for  steel  from  a  particular  producer  usually 

possesses  great  potential  elasticity.  In  other  wor.ds,  buyers  will 
readily  shift  from  one  producer  to  another  in  response  to  a  difference 
in  price.  This  is  due  to  the  informed  character  of  the  buying  of  steel. 
Buyers  have  excellent  technical  knowledge  of  the  product  to  be 
purchased;  and  since  nearly  all  steel  is  purchased  on  specification, 
the  identical  grade  and  type  of  steel  may  be  obtained  for  the  most 


13894  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

part  from  any  one  of  a  number  of  producers.  Furthermore,  the  large 
size  of  individual  purchases  makes  it  worth-while  for  buyers  to  shop 
for  the  lowest  possible  price. 

(4)  The  cost  structure  in  the  industry  is  marked  by  substantial  fixed  costs 

which  must  be  met  regardless  of  the  amount  of  steel  produced. *  Even 
more  significant  is  the  fact  indicated  by  the  operating  experience 
of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  over 
the  past  ten  years  that  the  additional  cost  per  unit  of  output  re- 
mains approximately  the  same  regardless  of  the  rate  of  operations 
provided  labor  rates,  prices  of  raw  materials,  etc.  remain  constant. 
As  a  result  of  these  two  characteristics  the  average  cost  of  each 
unit  of  the  entire  output  is  higher  than  the  additional  cost  per  addi- 
tional unit  of  output  for  practically  the  whole  range  of  operations 
up  to  the  limits  of  practical  capacity.  Finally,  the  cost  of  labor  and 
of  other  goods  and  services  purchased  from  others  (which  together 
constitute  about  80  percent  of  the  total  cost  in  the  case  of  the  sub- 
sidiaries of  United  States  Steel  Corporation),  are  largely  outside 
the  control  of  the  management  of  the  steel  producer. 

(5)  Producers  of  the  great  bulk  of  the  tonnage  of  steel  products  sold  in  the 

respective  consuming  areas  are  relatively  few  in  number. 

These  characteristics  of  the  steel  industry,  of  course,  do  not  coincide  with 
the  conditions  necessary  for  the  "perfect"  price  competition  of  classical  economic 
theory.  The  theory  of  "perfect"  price  competition,  for  example,  assumes  each 
buyer  and  seller  to  be  too  small  to  influence  the  market  price;  any  seller  is  supposed 
to  be  able  to  reduce  his  price  and  expand  his  production  without  fear  of  reactions 
on  the  part  of  competitors.  This  is  not  true  of  the  market  for  steel.  As  a  con- 
sequence of  potential  shiftability  of  buyers  in  response  to  price  concessions,  there 
is  an  incentive  to  obtain  business  bv  price  reduction  even  below  average  cost 
as  long  as  the  price  of  the  additional  units  so  sold  is  above  the  additional  cost 
thereof,  but  in  actual  competition  in  the  steel  industry  such  a  tenda,ricy  is  modified 
to  some  extent  by  the  difl3culty  of  continuing  to  offer  lower  prices  than  competitors 
since  competitors  meet  price  concessions  almost  immediately.  Furthermore, 
"perfect"  price  competition  does  not  take  into  account  the  consequences  of  the 
presence  in  the  market  of  relatively  few,  but  large,  buyers,  nor  the  size  of  their 
individual  orders.  It  overlooks  the  relative  difficulty  of  new  producers  entering 
the  market  and  many  other  factors  of  importance  in  the  competitive  situation  in 
the  steel  industry.  In  appraising  this  situation  it  should  be  recognized  that  the 
conditions  requisite  for  theoretically  "perfect"  price  condition  have  rarely,  if 
ever,  been  approached  in  any  industry,  and  could  never  be  generally  achieved 
in  a  manufacturing  industry  such  as  steel.  Accordingly,  it  is  hardly  reasonable 
to  judge  competitive  practives  in  the  steel  industry  by  imaginary  standards  based 
on  abstract  conditions  which  cannot  possibly  be  fulfilled,  and  which  probably 
never  have  been  fulfilled  in  any  industry. 

Waiving  the  reasonableness  of  the  application  of  the  criteria,  it  is  pertinent 
to  inquire  what  the  consequence  of  "perfect"  price  competition  would  be  in  the 
steel  industry.  If  such  a  theoretical  state  of  competition  prevailed,  each  producer 
would  take  aU  the  business  he  could  get  so  long  as  the  price  yielded  more  than 
the  additional  cost  of  producing  the  additional  ton  of  steel  so  sold.  If  the  demand 
exceeded  the  capacity  of  existing  producers,  the  price  of  steel  would  sky-rocket, 
being  limited  only  by  the  magnitude  of  the  demand.  If,  however,  the  demand 
declined  to  less  than  the  existing  capacity,  the  price  would  drop  abruptly  to  the 
level  of  the  additional  cost  per  additional  unit  of  the  least  efficient  producer 
remaining  in  the  market.  In  such  a  situation  producers  would  cover  little,  if 
any,  of  their  overhead.  Producers,  therefore,  would  be  operating  at  heavy 
losses  whenever  existing  capacity  was  not  being  fully  utilized,  and  would  recoup 
these  losses  by  high  prices  and  large  profits  during  the  peak  of  prosperity.  In 
major  depressions  the  efficient  as  well  as  the  marginal  concern  would  fail  to  sur- 
vive unless  it  had  accumulated  an  extraordinarily  large  cash  balance.'  Under 
such  conditions  existing  capacity  would  be  reduced  with  the  result  that  the  steel 
industry  would  become  a  bottle-neck  in  the  succeeding  rise  in  the  business  cycle 
by  limiting  the  possibility  of  increased  production  and  creating  a  premature 
boom  in  prices  before  the  rest  of  the  economy  could  achieve  full  employment. 

'  In  the  case  of  the  subsidiaries  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  these  costs  are  approximately  30% 
of  total  cost  at  40%  of  capacity  operations,  20%  at  70%  capacity  and  16%  at  100%  capacity. 

>  If  the  subsidiaries  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  sold  steel  at  a  price  only  equ-1  to  the  additional 
cost  of  additional  units  of  production,  It  Is  estimated  that  the  loss  to  the  Corporation  would  be  approximately 
$182,100,000  a  year.    Under  these  conditions  the  Corporation  could  not  survive  for  more  than  a  few  years. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13895 


Actually,  of  course,  these  characteristics  of  "perfect"  price  competition  would 
not  be  tolerated.  The  cut-throat  struggle  in  depression  and  the  sharp  increases 
in  prices  and  profits  in  prosperity,  as  well  as  the  bottle-neck  in  capacity,  would 
be  the  object  of  attacks  by  legislators,  economists  and  others. 

This  paper  is  an  attempt  to  outline  the  numberous  factors  involved  in  the  pricing 
of  steel  with  the  hope  that  a  re-statement  of  fundamentals  will  contribute  to  a 
clearer  understanding  of  prices  and  price  structure  in  the  steel  industry. 

The  Demand  fob  Steel 

immediate  source  op  demand 

Orders  for  steel  come  mostly  from  companies  using  the  products  of  the  steel 
ndustry  as  raw  materials  in  making  goods  or  as  equipment  in  producing  services. 

Companies  purchasing  steel  have  been  classified,  and  estimates  of  the  percentage 
of  the  total  steel  production  of  the  United  States  purchased  by  each  class  have 
been  made  as  follows: 

Percentage  Distribution  of  Hot  Rolled  Iron  and  Steel  Production  Among  Major 
Consuming  Industries  • 


Industry 

1938 

1932-38 
Average 

1926-31 
Average 

Automotive 

17.3 
18.8 
6.1 
9.1 
4.7 
7.4 
7.5 
3.5 
3.6 
1.6 
0.3 
20.1 

20.8 
16.0 
10.1 
8.4 
6.0 
6.0 
5.5 
4.2 
3.6 
0.9 
0.6 
18.0 

16  3 

Construction 

19.9 

Railroads 

17.9 

Container                          .                           ..         .... 

4.7 

Agriculture                                                    ..                .      . 

6  0 

Oil,  Oas  and  Water               -                             .                        

8.3 

Exports                             .                ....            ....        . 

6.9 

Machinery                         ..                                 

3.8 

ShipbuUding              .    „ 

0.9 

Mining     ::        :               :     : 

0.7 

Miscellaneous                                                 .... 

'15.6 

<  M.  W.  Worthing,  Distribution  of  Steel  Products  to  Major  Consuming  Industrie',  United  States  Steel 
Corporation,  October  30,  1939.  Computations  made  by  apportioning  Individual  hot-rolled  product 
totals  on  the  basis  of  Iron  Age  distribution  reports  and  by  allocating  jobber  snipments  to  ultimate  con- 
sumers. 

»  "Miscellaneous"  for  the  period  1926-31  includes  "Furniture  and  Furnishings." 


la  connection  with  the  above  classification  interesting  observations  may  be 
made.  First,  the  purchasers  of  steel  are  principally  companies  engaged  in  the 
production  of  producers'  and  consumers'  durable  goods.  An  exception  is  the 
container  industry  which  manufactures  tin  cans,  an  article  classified  as  a  perishable 
good  since  it  is  generally  used  but  once  and  discarded.  Second,  in  recent  years 
there  has  been  a  marked  increase  in  the  percentage  of  steel  purchased  by  con- 
sumers' durable  goods  industries,  such  as  the  automotive  and  household  appliance 
industries,  and  a  decrease  in  the  percentage  of  steel  purchased  by  producers, 
durable  goods  industries,  such  as  the  railroad  industry.  In  this  connection  "Mis- 
cellaneous," which  has  shown  such  rapid  growth",  includes  many  industries  pro- 
ducing consumers'  durable  goods  such  as  refrigerators,  air  conditioning  units, 
stoves,  etc.  Third,  "Exports"  in  some  years  account  for  an  appreciable  amount 
of  total  steel  sold.  Since  the  economics  of  export  trade  involves  conditions  not 
present  in  the  domestic  market,  the  subject  of  prices  and  pricing  methods  in  the 
steel  export  trade  have  not  been  included  in  this  study. 

Most  industries  purchasing  steel  are  characterized  by  large  companies;  in  the 
automotive,  container,  agricultural  implements,  household  durable  goods  and 
shipbuilding  industries,  a  relatively  few  large  companies  comprise  a  substantial 
percentage  of  the  total  production  of  their  respective  industries.'  In  purchasing 
their  steel  requirements  these  large  companies  usually  come  into  the  market  with 
orders  of  considerable  magnitude.  The  demand  for  steel  therefore  consists,  to  a 
great  degree,  in  large-sized  orders  placed  by  relatively  few  companies.* 

•  Big  Business:  Its  Growth  and  Its  Place,  Chart  3,  p.  42  (Twentieth  Century  Fund.)  Exhibit  No.  8S8 
submitted  to  the  T.  N.  E.  C,  July  11, 1939,  (based  on  Census  of  Manufactures). 

« Sales  statistics  of  the  subsidiaries  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  show  that  In  1937, 941  customers  bad 
billings  over  $100,000  each  and  accounted  for  73%  of  gross  sales;  In  1938, 663  customers  had  billings  over  $100,000 
each  and  accounted  for  68%  of  gross  sales. 


13896  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

GBOGBAPHIC    DISTRIBUTION 

Orders  for  steel  arise  for  the  most  part  in  concentrated  geographical  areas.  The 
bulk  of  tonnage  business  originates  in  a  belf  extending  east  of  the  Mississippi, 
and  north  of  the  Ohio  rivers,  tapering  ofif  toward  Philadelphia  and  New  York; 
but  important  markets  exist  outside  this  zone,  particularly  for  products  required 
by  the  oil  and  canning  industries.  Although  major  markets  for  particular  steel 
products  vary  both  as  to  location  and  degree  of  importance,  the  principal  centers 
of  the  composite  demand  for  steel  in  their  general  order  of  precedence  are:  * 

1.  Detroit  6.  Youngstown  11.  Cincinnati 

2.  Chicago-Gary  7.  Milwaukee  12.  Houston 

3.  Pittsburgh  8.  San  Francisco  13.  Buffalo 

4.  Cleveland  9.  Newark  14.  St.  Louis 

5.  Los  Angeles  10.  New  York  15.  Toledo 

Characteristics  of  Demand 

The  demand  for  steel  is  subject  to  tremendous  cyclical  fluctuations.  This  is  due 
primarily  to  the  great  cyclical  fluctuations  in  the  demand  for  producers'  and 
consumers'  durable  goods  in  the  manufacture  of  which  steel  is  consumed. 

DEBIVteD   nature   OF   DEMAND 

The  demand  for  new  durable  goods  is  highly  sensitive  to  changes  in  the  demand 
for  services  which  the  durable  goods  perform.  This  may  be  demonstrated  by  a 
simple  theoretical  illustration.  A  railroad  needs  five  hundred  cars  filled  to  ca- 
pacity to  carry  10,000,000  passengers  a  year.  Each  year  fifty  cars  normally  wear 
out  and  are  replaced.  More  people  decide  to  travel  by  railroad  and  passenger 
traffic  increases  10  percent,  so  that  11,000,000  passengers  a  year  must  be  accom- 
modated. T  lis  requires  fifty  more  cars  which  must  be  acquired  .immediately  to 
meet  the  inc?  3ased  demand  for  passenger  service.  Therefore,  in  the  year  that  this 
increase  occurs  the  railroad  has  to  buy  one  hundred  cars  instead  of  the  fifty 
usually  purchased  for  the  normal  replacement  program.  Thus  a  10  percent  in- 
crease in  the  demand  for  passenger  service  results  in  a  100  percent  increase  in  the 
demand  for  railroad  passenger  cars.  This  is  sometimes  called  by  economists  the 
"acceleration  principle."  It  works  in  reverse  too.  If  passenger  traffic  decreased 
10  percent  there  would  not  be  any  demand  at  all  for  new  passenger  railroad  cars; 
5ince  only  four  hundred  and  fifty  cars  would  be  required  to  carry  the  9,000,000 
passengers  left,  no  additional  cars  would  be  needed  to  replace  the  fifty  worn  out. 
[n  other  words,  a  10  percent  decrease  in  demand  for  passenger  service  would  cause 
a  100  percent  decrease  in  the  demand  for  new  durable  goods  to  perform  such 
service. 

DURABILITY  AND  DEMAND 

The  longer  the  life  of  durable  goods  the  more  sensitive  is  the  demand  for  the 
new  durable  goods  to  changes  in  the  demand  for  services.  For  example,  in  the 
simple  theoi-etical  illustration  given  above  the  average  life  of  the  railroad  car  was 
presumed  to  be  ten  years.  Fifty  cars  normally  had  to  be  replaced  annually. 
However,  if  the  average  life  had  been  five  years,  100  cars  per  annum  would  have 
to  be  replaced.  In  that  event  a  10  percent  increase  in  the  demand  for  passenger 
service  would  have  resulted  in  only  a  50  percent  increase  in  the  demand  for  new 
railroad  cars,  and  a  10  percent  decrease  in  the  demand  would  have  resulted  in  a 
50  percent  decrease  in  the  demand  for  new  equipment.  On  the  other  hand,  if  the 
average  life  of  a  car  had  been  twenty  years,  only  twenty-five  cars  would  have  to 
be  replaced  annually.  Therefore  a  10  percent  increase  in  the  demand  for  service 
would  have  caused  200  percent  increase  in  the  demand  for  new  railroad  cars. 
In  the  event  of  a  10  percent  decrease  in  the  d'^mand  for  service,  the  replacement 
demand  for  new  equipment  would  not  only  disappear  entirely,  but  twenty-five 
additional  cars  theoretically  would  be  removed  from  service  and  be  available  to 
meet  the  normal  replacement  demand  in  the  following  year. 

Thus,  while  the  demand  for  new  durable  goods  is  highly  sensitive  to  change  in 
the  demand  for  services  which  the  durable  goods  perform,  the  degree  of  such 
sensitivit.v  and  the  magnitude  of  the  resultant  fluctuation    in  demand  depends  on 

>  Based  on  estimates  made  in  1937  for  the  subsidiaries  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  of  a  "normal" 
Industry-wide  market  for  the  following  products:  heavy  rails:  heavy  structural  shapes;  plates,  sheared  and 
oaiversal:  fabricated  otructural  work;  merchant  bars,  including  reinforced  concrete  bars  and  Ught  structural 
Ihares:  black  sheets;  galvanised  sheets;  hot  rolled  strip;  rods,  wire  and  wire  products;  tin  mil'  products; 
pipe  and  tubing. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13897 

the  life  span  of  the  durable  goods;  fluctuations  in  the  d.  mand  for  new  du  able 
goods  will  be  progressively  greater  as  durability  increases.  In  actual  practice 
many  qualifications  to  this  principle  exist,*  nevertheless  it  is  fundamental  in  the 
demand  for  durable  goods. 

POSTPONABILITY  OF  PURCHASE  OF  DURABLE  GOODS 

The  purchase  of  durable  goods  usually  can  be  easily  postponed,  and  is  postponed 
when  income  is  scant  or  prospects  for  the  profitable  use  of  additional  durable  goods 
are  discouraging.  As  a  result  of  postponability  of  purchase,  producers'  durable 
goods  industries  feel  an  immediate  effect  on  demand  resulting  from  the  con- 
traction of  producers'  income  as  expenditures  for  capital  goods  are  deferred  and 
the  income  of  the  purchaser  is  directed  primarily  to  meeting  necessary  out-of- 
pocket  expenses.  In  addition,  even  though  the  immediate  business  outlook  is 
favorable,  expenditures  for  capital  equipment  may  be  postponed  if  the  long  term 
business  outlook  is  unfavorable;  the  business  man  must  anticipate  a  reasonable 
return  over  the  life  of  the  investment  before  tying  up  his  capital  in  durable  equip- 
ment. After  a  prolonged  depression,  with  purchases  of  durable  goods  almost 
completely  eliminated,  increased  profits  and  returning  confidence  as  to  the  future 
may  stimulate  a  great  upward  surge  in  the  demand  for  replacements  previously 
postponed  and  also  for  new  equipment  for  expansion. 

In  like  manner,  consumers'  durable  goods  industries  feel  the  impact  of  declining 
consumer  income,  as  funds  available  are  used  to  buy  the  necessities  of  life  and 
existing  consumers'  durable  goods,  such  as  automobiles,  are  made  to  last  longer 
than  anticipated,  or  are  discarded  without  replacement  under  stringent  con- 
ditions. Increased  consumer  income,  actual  and  anticipated,  will  create  a  strong 
revival  in  demand  for  consumers'  durable  goods  as  replacements  are  made  and 
new  equipment  purchased. 

As  previously  indicated,  the  "acceleration  principle"  becomes  more  potent  as 
durability  of  a  product  increases.  As  a  result  the  magnitude  of  expansion  and 
contraction  in  demand  for  products  of  the  durable  goods  industries  will  be  greater 
than  for  non-durable  goods  industries.  These  fluctuations  of  demand  for  ne\'/ 
durable  goods  will  be  further  magnified  by  the  postponability  of  purchase  of  these 
goods;  a  producer  wUl  buy  coal,  oil  or  electrical  energy  long  after  he  has  decided 
he  must  postpone  purchase  of  capital  equipment,  and  a  consumer  must  buy  food, 
clothing  and  other  necessities  even  though  he  cannot  afford  a  new  car  or  a 
refrigerator. 

TOTAL   DEMAND    FOR   STEEL   IS   INELASTIC 

The  magnitude  of  these  cyclical  fluctuations  in  demand  cannot  be  materially 
affected  by  adjustments  in  the  price  of  steel  because  the  total  demand  for  steel 
is  itfelastic.  This  is  due,  first,  to  the  derived  nature  of  the  demand  for  steel,  and, 
second,  to  the  limited  number  of  substitutes  for  basic  steel  products,  and  con- 
versely the  limited  number  of  products  for  which  steel  may  be  substituted. 

As  previously  indicated,  the  demand  for  steel  is  derived  from  the  demand  for 
the  services  which  products  made  of  steel  perform.  If  a  change  in  the  price  of 
steel  is  to  influence  the  demand  for  the  finished  product  in  which  the  steel  is  used, 
two  conditions  must  exist:  the  cost  of  steel  must  represent  a  substantial  per- 
centage of  the  selling  price  of  the  finished  article,  and  the  demand  for  the  finished 
article  itself  must  be  such  that  it  responds  to  changes  in  its  price.  This  is  not 
generally  the  case;  steel  as  a  raw  material  usually  represents  a  small  percentage  of 
the  total  cost  of  the  finished  iproduct,  and  the  major  industries  purchasing  steel 
have  a  rather  inelastic  demand  for  their  products.' 

The  automotive  industry,  which  during  recent  years  has  been  the  largest  single 
customer  of  the  steel  industry,  is  a  typical  example  of  the  derived  nature  of  the 
demand  for  steel  and  the  resultant  inelasticity  of  such  demand.  The  cost  of  steel 
in  a  low-priced  automobile  retailing  between  $700.00  and  $800.00  is  about  $85.00, 
or  roughly  10  percent  of  the  retail  price.     Roos  and  von  Szeliski  in  a  recent  study 

'  (a)  The  actual  age  distribution  of  the  stock  of  durable  goods  in  use  might  change  in  dlflerent  years 

(b)  The  effect  of  obsolescence  is  to  increase  replacement  rates  and  therefore  limit  the  magnitude  of  fluctua- 
tions, if  it  is  a  constant  factor  from  year  to  year.  If  an  erratic  factor,  it  would  increase  the  fluctuations  if  It 
occurred  in  normal  or  above  normal  years,  or  if  it  occurred  in  sub-normal  years  it  would  limit  the  fluctuation. 

(c)  For  producers'  durable  goods,  obsolescence  can  be  brought  about  by  shifts  in  demand,  the  development 
of  new  products,  the  introduction  of  new  techniques  of  production,  discovery  of  new  resources  or  new  meth- 
ods of  using  resources,  migration  of  industry  from  one  afea  to  another,  and  similar  changes.  In  the  field  of 
consumers'  durable  goods,  style  changes  and  shifts  in  consumers'  demands  are  among  the  causes  which  may 
result  in  shortening  the  otherwise  useful  life  of  durable  goods. 

">  The  approximate  proportion  of  steel  cost  in  price  of  finished  product  for  various  items  is  as  follows: 
mile  of  railroad,  36.7.%;  apartment  building,  10%;  automobile,  10%;  can  of  food,  8%;  frame  house,  6.2%; 
electric  refrigerator,  3.4%;  dairy  barn,  3.2%;  mile  of  reinforced  highway,  0.7%. 


13898  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

contained  in  "The  Dynamics  of  Automobile  Demand"  »  estimated  1.5  to  be  a 
representative  average  of  elasticity  of  demand  for  new  automobiles;  i.  e.,  for 
every  1  percent  decrease  in  the  price,  the  automobiles  sold  would  increase  1.5 
percent.  Since  steel  costs  represent  10  percent  Qf  retail  price,  a  5  percent  decrease 
in  steel  prices  would  permit  a  0.5  percent  reduction  in  the  price  of  automobiles, 
and  according  to  such  elasticity  of  demand. would  increase  automobile  sales  to  the 
extent  of  0.75  percent.  The  resultant  increase  in  the  demand  for  steel  by  the 
automobile  industry  would  be  neghgible. 

EFFECT    OF   THE   SUBSTITUTION    FACTOB 

Substitution  of  steel  for  other  materials,  or  a  reverse  substitution,  is  not  an 
important  factor  in  the  cyclical  fluctuations  in  the  demand  for  steel.  If,  through 
lower  prices,  steel  could  invade  a  major  market  served  by  other  products,  or  if 
high  relative  steel  prices  meant  invasion  of  major  steel  markets  by  substitute 
products,  there  would  be  imparted  to  the  total  demand  for  steel  a  degree  of 
elasticity  not  now  present.  Steel  possesses  more  physical  strength  per  dollar 
of  investment  than  any  other  existing  product;  wood  and  concrete  have  a  restricted 
field  in  which  they  may  be  substituted  for  heavy  steel.  Glass,  plastics,  rubber, 
alxmiinum  and  certain  alloys  may  serve  as  substitutes  in  specialized  fields;  but 
even  in  these  cases  price  may  be  only  one  of  many  competitive  factors  involved. 
Therefore,  price  reduction  would  result  in  very  little  additional  steel  being  sold 
as  substitutes  for  other  products,  and  a  price  advance,  unless  abnormal,  probably 
would  not  result  in  additional  competition  from  substitute  products. 

POTENTIAL    ELASTICITY    OF    DEMAND    FROM    A    PABTICULAR   PBODUCEB 

Although  the  over-all  demand  for  steel  is  inelastic  and  the  total  quantity  bought 
would  not  be  substantially  different  if  the  price  within  reasonable  limits  were 
lower  or  higher,  the  demand  for  steel  from  a  particular  producer  possesses  great 
potential  elasticity.  This  readiness  of  a  buyer  to  sh\ft  from  one  producer  to 
another  because  of  a  lower  price  is  due  to  the  informed  character  of  the  buying 
of  steel.  Technical  knowledge  of  the  product  to  be  purchased  is  available  through 
laboratories  of  individual  purchasers,  trade  associations  and  independent  research 
agencies;  exactly  the  same  steel  may,  for  the  most  part,  be  obtained  from  any  one 
of  a  number  of  producers.  Furthermore,  the  large  size  of  individual  purchases 
makes  it  worth-while  for  buyers  to  seek  the  lowest  possible  price.  This  propensity 
to  shop  is  enhanced  by  knowledge  of  latest  price  quotations,  by  familiarity  with 
psychological  and  other  factors  resulting  in  a  "buyers"  or  a  "sellers"  market  for 
aU  or  particular  prodiicts,  and  by  a  general  understanding  of  approximate  costs 
of  steel  production ;  indeed,  a  few  purchasers »  of  steel  operate  completely  inte- 
grated steel  works  to  supply  a  portion  of  their  requirements,  and  others  i"  have 
semi-integrated  and  non-integrated  capacity. 

Thus,  potentially,  the  demand  for  steel  from  an  individual  producer  is'elastic 
and  buyers  are  often  in  a  position  to  exert  bargaining  pressure  to  obtain  the  lowest 
possible  prices,  especially  when  the  steel  industry  is  not  operating  near  capacity. 

The  Supply  of  Steel 

geographic  concentration 

The  most  economical  source  of  steel  is  that  location  at  which  the  raw  materials 
can  be  assembled,  the  steel  produced  and  delivery  to  the  market  effected  at  the 
lowest  possible  total  cost.  In  determining  plant  location  '^  assembly  costs  are 
most  important;  more  than  four  tons  of  raw  materials  must  be  assembled  for  every 
ton  of  steel  produced,  i^though  production  costs  are  subject  to  variations  due 
primarily  to  geographical  wage  rate  differentials,  these  variations  are  supple- 
mentary to  and,  in  a  measure,  compensatory  for  otherwise  uneconomical  assembly 
or  delivery  costs. 

The  approximate  amounts  of  principal  raw  materials  required  per  ton  of  pig 
iron  are:  4075  pounds  of  iron  ore  (assuming  ore  of  a  reasonably  high  metallic 
content),  2700  pounds  of  coking  coal  and  900  pounds  of  limestone.  Another  1500 
pounds  of  coal  may  be  consumed  for  power  and  heating  before  a  ton  of  finished 

'  Publication  of  the  General  Motors  Corporation  based  upon  papers  presented  at  a  Joint  meeting  of  the 
American  Statistical  Association  and  the  Econometric  Society  in  Detroit,  Michigan,  on  December  27, 1938. 

'  Ford  Motor  Company  and  International  Harvester  Company. 

'•  American  Car  and  Foundry  Co.;  American  Locomotive  Co.;  Atchison,  Topeka  and  Santa  Fe  Railroad 
Co.;  Continental  Can  Co.;  Simonds  Saw  and  Steel  Co.;  Tlmken  Roller  Bearing  Co.,  Inc. 

"  Availability  of  a  large  water  supply  Is  important  In  steel  mill  location. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13899 

aieel  product  has  left  the  mills.  The  greater  proportion  of  the  raw  materials  is 
used  in  the  blast  furnace,  but  integrated  steel  works  have  developed  from  blast 
furnace  plants  because  (a)  as  steel  approaches  the  finished  stage  the  cost  of  ship- 
ment becomes  a  smaller  percentage  of  the  cost  of  the  product  to  the  buyer;  (b) 
integration  assures  more  constant  and  reasonably  full  utilization  of  blast  furnaces 
and  open  hearths;  (c)  economies  of  converting  molten  iron  into  steel  and  other 
heat  conservation  factors  are  important  in  the  economical  production  of  steel'. 

Limitations  imposed  by  the  necessity  for  the  most  favorable  combination  of 
assembly,  production  and  delivery  costs  have  confined  steel  production  to  a  few 
geographical  areas. 

The  most  favorable  combination  of  the  three  variables  is  probably  to  be  found 
at  Lake  Erie  and  Lake  Michigan  ports  and  in  the  Pittsburgh  district  (including 
.the  Mahoning  and  Ohio  Valleys) .  These  locations  '^  were  primarily  determined 
by  the  assembly  costs  of  Lake  Superior  ores  which  are  the  backbone  of  the  steel 
industry  in  the  United  States  and  supply  about  82  percent  of  the  ore  consumed  in 
the  country,  and  of  the  finest  metallurgical  coking  coals  which  are  found  in  Western 
Pennsylvania,  West  Virginia  and  Kentucky.  The  assembly  cost. of  lirnestone, 
which  is  well  distributed  and  the  least  important  of  the  major  raw  materials,  is 
usually  an  incidental  factor. 

Comparative  assembly  costs  at  principal  production  centers  in  this  area  have 
been  estimated  as  follows: 

Estimated  Assembly  Costs  in  the  Production  of  Pig  Iron,  Summer  of  19S7  ' 
[In  dollars  per  gross  ton  of  pig  iron] 


Iron  Ore 

Coal 

Flux 

Total 

Annual  Blast-Furnace 
Capacity 

Producing  Center 

Thousands 

of  Gross 

Tons 

Percentage 

.ofU.8 

Total 

Weirton-Steubenville _ . 

$5,508 
5.804 
3.497 
3.497 
3.497 
6.193 
3.487 

$0,468 
0.284 
2.714 
2.909 
3.249 
1.979 
3.867 

$0,337 
0.337 
0.241 
0.241 
0.086 
0.170 
0.241 

$6,313 
6.425 
6.452 
6.647 
6.832 
7.342 
7.595 

2,093 
11, 521 
2,685 
3,267 
1,423 
6,592 
10,266 

Pittsburgh _._ __.. 

Cleveland 

Buffalo - ._.. 

Detroit ._ 

Youngstown 

23.0 
6.4 
6.5 
2.8 
13.2 
20.5 

Chicago 

Total 

1  Worthing,  Marion,  "Coiaparative  Assembly  Costs  in  the  Manufacture  of  Pie  Iron",  Pittsburgh  Btisinest 
Review,  v.  VIII.,  No.  1,  January  31,  1938,  Pp.  21-25,  Table  1. 


Assembly  costs  at  these  locations  vary;  the  importance  of  each  component  of 
the  costs  is  emphasized  by  the  difference  of  $1,17  in  favor  of  Pittsburgh  over  Chicago 
due  entirely  to  Pittsburgh's  fortunate  position  in  the  center  of  the  finest  metallur- 
gical coking  coal  fields  in  the  country. 

Although  primarily  based  upon  assembly  costs,  the  growth  of  these  great  steel 
production  centers  to  their  present  size  would  not  have  been  possible  if  outlets 
fop  at  least  a  considerable  part  of  their  products  did  not  exist  fairly  close  at  hand; 
aU  the  production  centers,  coincide  with,  or  are  adjacent  to,  major  centers  of  steel 
demand.  However,  the  location  of  these  production  centers  depends  only  in  part 
on  relative  assembly  costs  and  the  magnitude  of  local  demand  for  a  particular 
product;  it  depends,  among  other  thngs,  on  the  conformation  of  the  market  for 
each  product  and  for  the  group  of  products  that  may  be  economically  produced 
together." 

For  example,  hot  rolled  sheets,  cold  rolled  sheets  and  tin  plate,  which  are 
produced  at  the  Gary  sheet  and  tin  mills  of  a  subsidiary  of  United  States  Steel 
Corporation  with  a'll  the  attendant  economies  of  large  scale  production,  are  products 
of  virtually  the  same  integrated  process.  Major  outlets  for  hot  rolled  sheets  are 
Chicago,  Detroit,  and  Indiana  with  important  sources  of  demand  in  Iowa,  Minne- 
sota, and  Ohio;  Detroit  is  the  principal  market  for  cold  rolled  sheets,  and  Chicago 

"  Although  Pittsburgh  historically  was  established  as  a  steel  producing  center  before  Lake  Superior  ores 
and  coking  coal  came  into  general  use,  its  growth  and  the  maintenance  of  its  dominant  position  has  been 
based  on  its  economical  accessibility  to  these  resources. 

'3  Committee  on  Iron  and  Steel  Price  Research,  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research  Conference  on 
Price  Research,  Proposa.'i /or  Research  on  Prices  and  Pricing  Policies  in  the  Iron  and  Steel  Industry  (1939). 

124491 — 41— pt.  26 21 


13900  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

is  an  important  market  for  tin  palate.  A  similar  situation  exists  at  the  Irvin 
Works  of  this  same  subsidiary  in  the  Pittsburgh  district  which  rolls  the  same  three 
products.  Ohio  and  adjacent  West  Virginia  counties,  Pittsburgh  and  Philadelphia 
are  maior  markets  for  its  hot  rolled  sheets.  Cold  rolled  sheets  are  principally 
shipped  to  Cleveland,  other  Ohio  centers  and  Philadelphia.  The  Irvin  Works 
may  also  supplement  Gary  in  the  Detroit  market  with  hot  and  cold  rolled  sheets 
in  periods  of  peak  demand,  while  Metropolitan  New  York  is  the  major  market 
for  its  large  ouput  of  tin  plate. 

This  market  structure  of  groups  of  products  that  may  economically  be  produced 
together  accounts  in  part  for  production  patterns  with  such  apparent  inconsisten- 
cies as  limited  capacity  at  Detroit  and  excess  capacity,  as  compared  to  local  de- 
mand, at  Pittsburgh.  The  effects  of  historical  development  and  the  immobility 
of  steel  making  equipment  will  be  discussed  later. 

Birmingham,  Alabama,  and  vicinity  is  another  location  with  a  favorable 
combination  of  assembly  and  production  costs.  Assembly  costs  at  Birmingham 
are  undoubtedly  the  lowest  in  the  country — iron  ore,  coal  and  flux  being  in  close 
proximity.  In  this  case  low  assembly  costs  compensate  in  part  for  the  com- 
paratively poor  quality  of  the  raw  materials;  iron  content  of  the  ores  is  low  and 
phosphorous  content  high,  making  conditioning  and  sintering  desirable;  the  coal 
requires  washing  before  coking.  With  wage  rates  lower  than  other  districts, 
production  costs  are  also  economical,  although  basic  wage  rates  have  been  rising 
in  the  South.  These  advantages  of  assembly  and  production  costs  are  offset  by  re- 
moteness from  major  markets;  a  substantial  part  of  the  tin  plate  produced  at  the 
large  plant  recently  er^ted  by  Tennessee  Coal,  Iron  &  Railroad  Company, 
another  subsidiary  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  at  Fairfield,  Alabama,  is 
shipped  to  the  West  Coast  and  Hawaii. 

Sparrows  Point,  Maryland,  is  strategigally  located.  Based  on  the  use  of 
high  grade  imported  ores,  iron  ore  costs  have  been  estimated  "  to  be  less  at 
Sparrows  Point  than  at  Lake  Erie  and  Pittsburgh  area  plants,  which  advantage 
is  offset,  in  part  at  least,  by  higher  assembly  costs  for  coal  and  limestone.  Its 
accessibility  to  the  large  markets  of  the  eastern  seaboard,  and  its  ability  to  com- 
pete on  the  West  Coast  via  all-water  transportation  due  to  tidewater  facilities, 
make  economical  distribution  costs  a  major  factor  in  the  favorable  location  of 
Sparrows  Point. 

Combined  assembly,  production  and  delivery  costs  make  possibldi  integrated 
steel  production  on  a  commercial  basis  in  only  one  other  geographical  area  at  the 
present  time;  '^  Colorado  and  Utah  both  possess  iron  ore,  fair  coking  coal  and 
limestone  in  sufficient  quantities  and  within  reasonable  assembly  distance  of 
each  other.  Due  to  prohibitive  distribution  costs,  however,  this  district  must 
depend,  in  the  main,  on  local  demand  for  special  products.  At  Pueblo,  Colorado, 
the  Colorado  Fuel  and  Iron  Corporation,  cognizant  of  this  situation,  produces 
principally  rails  and  track  accessories  for  Western  roads,  and  wire  products  for 
farm  and  ranch  consumption.  At  Ironton,  Utah,  the  Columbia  Steel  Company, 
a  subsidia>y  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  operates  a  blast  furnace  whose 
pig  iron  output  is  taken  in  part  by  its  West  Coast  steel  mills  near  Los  Angeles 
and  San  Francisco  and  in  part  by  local  buyers.  California  steel  mills  also  use  a 
considerable  amount  of  scrap  obtained  locally. 

Although  it  is  an  important  steel  consuming  area,  the  West  Coast  cannot  sup- 
port more  than  limited  steel  making  capacity  due  to  high  assembly  costs,  par- 
ticularly in  the  face  of  competition  from  Birmingham  and  Sparrows  Point,  both 
of  which  can  serve  this  area  on  a  more  economical  basis. 

The  principal  steel  producing  centers  of  the  nation,  therefore,  are  confined  to 
particular  geographical  areas  where  the  raw  materials  for  steel  making  can  be 
economically  assembled.  Differences  in  the  development  and  activity  of  these 
producing  areas  have  been  determined  to  a  considerable  extent  by  the  relative 
costs  of  transporting  steel  to  consuming  areas.  Many  small  non-integrated 
mills,  howeyer,  are  located  outside  the  major  producing  areas  where  they  may 
use  local  scrap,  merchant  pig  iron  or  semi-finished  steel  to  produce  steel  for  con- 
sumption in  the  local  area  or  may  specialize  in  particular  products  to  distribute  in 
more  widespread  markets'. 

t"  Maryland  State  Planning  Commission,  The  Iron  and  Steel  Industry— Float  Furnaces,  Steel  Works  and 
Rolling  Mills,  November  1938,  p.  14. 

'»  With  the  exception  of  certain  areas  with  small  local  ore  deposits,  capable  of  supporting  limited  operations, 
i.  e.,  ore  deposits  of  New  Jersey,  Eastern  Pennsylvania,  and  the  Adirondacks,  economically  accessible  to 
Pennsylvania  coal  fields. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13901 

TECHNOLOGICAL   ASPECTS 

Steel  making  equipment  installed  at  the  producing  centers  is  both  costly  and 
immobile;  the  economies  of  size  inherent  in  steel  manufacture  have  been  important 
factors  in  determining  the  design  of  modern  mills.  The  result  is  that  the  small 
plants  of  fifty  years  ago  have  been  succeeded  by  complex  and  gigantic  operating 
units. 

Twenty  years  ago  the  coke  used  m  blast  furnaces  was  principally  made  in  banks 
of  simple  beehive  ovens,  usually  located  at  the  mine.  Today,  it  is  made  at  or 
near  the  steel  plant  in  long  batteries  of  by-product  coke  ovens  with  alternating 
coking  and  heating  chambers  topped  by  coal  larries,  off-takes  and  collecting  mains. 
In  close  proximitj'  stand  the  tall  cooling  towers  and  scrubbers,  the  ammonia  house 
and  benzol  plant  used  to  obtain  dumerous  by-products  from  the  tars  and  gases 
emanating  from  the  coking  ovens,  which  are  today  recovered  and  put  to  use. 

In  1880  the  capacity  of  the  most  efficient  blast  furnace,  a  comparatively  simple 
unit,  was  one  hundred  tons  per  day;  at  present  the  newest  and  most  eflicient 
furnaces  are  rated  at  1100  to  1200  tons  per  day.  This  increased  output  has  been 
accomplished  not  only  by  increase  in  size  and  better  blast  furnace  practice,  but 
by  mechanical  improvements  and  the  development  of  auxiliary  equipment.  A 
blast  furnace  plant  today  is  enormous  and  complicated.  The  furnace  is  a  tall 
circular  structure  90  to  100  feet  high,  built  of  firebrick  and  reinforced  externally 
by  a  close-fitting  steel  shell.  It  is  provided  with  apparatus  for  hoisting  iron  ore, 
coke  and  limestone  to  the  top  where  they  are  charged  into  the  furnace.  Large 
pipes  carry  the  gas  generated  in  the  furnace  to  the  stoves  where  it  is  used  for 
heating  purposes.  Beside  each  furnace  stand  four  cylindrical  stoves  nearly 
as  high  as  the  furnace  itself.  These  stoves  heat  air  to  high  temperatures  before 
it  is  blown  into  the  furnace  at  the  rate  of  five  tons  of  air  for  every  ton  of  iron 
produced.  The  impurities  in  the  raw  material  are  either  burned  out  or  accumu- 
lated in  the  slag  which  gathers  on  top  of  the  molten  metal.  This  slag  is  removed 
through  the  higher  of  two  tapping  holes.  Through  another  tapping  hole  the 
molten  iron  is  drawn  at  periodic  intervals  either  into  ladles  to  be  carried  to  huge 
containers  known  as  mixers  subsequently  to  be  taken  to  the  open  hearth  and 
Bessemer  converters,  or  into  runners  leading  to  the  pig  iron  casting  beds.  A 
boiler  house,  power  plant,  pumping  station,  tflrbo-blower,  stockyard,  ore  bridge, 
car  dumper  and  raw  material  bins,  all  constitute  important  parts  of  blast  f'urnace 
equipment.  . 

The  steel  making  equipment  is  equally  complex  and  has  increased  in  size  as  it 
has  become  more  efficient.  In  1899  the  average  open  hearth  furnace  had  a 
capacity  of  22  tons  per  heat;  in  1938  the  average  furnace  capacity  was  95  tons 
per  heat  and  the  largest  400  tons  per  heat.  Even  more  spectacular  has  been  the 
radical  improvement  in  design  and  the  increase  in  size  of  continuous  rolling  mills 
for  flat  rolled  products  in  recent  years.  This  acceleration  of  growth  has  been  so 
dramatic  that  in  1936  a  continuous  rolling  mill  with  a  capacity  of  as  much  as 
600,000  tons  of  finished  flat  rolled  steel  per  year  was  unprecedented;  yet  in  March 
1938  a  continuous  strip  mill  was  opened  with  an  annual  capacity  of  approximately 
one  million  tons." 

Equipment  used  in  each  stage  of  modern  steel  making  is  usually  so  combined 
as  to  perform  a  series  of  vertically  integrated  operations;  conservation  of  heat 
and  power  requires  continuous  processes.  Assurance  of  adequate  sources  of  raw 
material  and  the  elimination  of  purchasing  expenses  at  each  stage  of  operations 
are  important  factors  in  promoting  further  integration. 

Vertical  integration  is  a  dual  development  in  the  industry.  Non-integrated 
and  semi-integrated  producers  desiring  independence  from  producers  of  semi- 
finished steel  and  the  owners  of  raw  material  reserves,  and  influenced  by  the 
possibility  of  additional  savings,  integrate  toward  the  sources  of  their  raw  materials. 
Partly  as  a  result  of  such  movement  and  partly  due  to  the  dechne  in  demand  for 
steel  used  in  producers'  durable  goods  industries,  producers  of  semi-finished  and 
heavy  steel  have  obtained  outlets  for  their  productive  capacity  by  integration 
towards  more  highly  finished  products. 

CAPITAL    INVESTMENT    REQUIREMENTS 

This  combination  of  huge  uriits  vertixially  integrated  requires  large  capital 
investment.  A  modern  blast  furnace  of  about  1,000  tons  capacity  with  the 
auxihary  equipment  above  m  utioned  costs  four  to  five  million  dollars.     The 

i«  Republic  Steel  Company  continuous  strip  mill,  Cuyahoga  Valley,  Ohio. 


139D2  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

average  investment  required  for  a  modern  steel  works  of  efficient  size  is  approxi- 
mately $100,000,000.  Such  a  mill  would  be  capable  of  producing  about  1,000,000 
tons  of  ingots  per  annum  and  would  have  diversified  finishing  equipment  of  suffi- 
cient capacity  to  con  vert  about  half  the  output  into  billets  and  other  semi-finished 
steel  and  the  other  half  into  sheets  and  strip.  Such  an  investment  would  not 
include  operations  prior  to  the  assembly  of  raw  materials  at  the  plant  site,  i.  e., 
the  plant  would  be  integrated  only  from  coke  plant  to  continuous  rolling  mills. 
Operating  units  may  be  and  sometimes  are  much  larger;  a  single  continuous  hot 
and  cold  rolling  finishing  plant  alone  may  require  an  investment  of  $60,000,000. 
Such  large  and  complex  equipment  cannot  be  moved  in  response  to  geographical 
shifts  in  demand,  and  only  extraordinarily  great  differential  advantages  of  a  new 
location  j  ustify  scrapping  existing  facilities  embodying  large  unamortized  invest- 
ment and  long  remaining  service  life.  New  areas  of  demand  usually  develop  only 
for  particular  products  or  groups  of  products  and  it  may  be  more  economical  for 
the  established  producer  to  install  sufficient  capacity  at  the  existing  location  to 
compete  in  the  new  markets  than  to  build  integrated  steel  works  at  the  source  of 
the  new  demand.  This  decision  may  depend  first,  on  the  combination  of  products 
that  can  be  economically  produced  together,  and  second,  on  whether  the  steel 
demanded  can  be  produced  by  integrating  new  facilities  with  unused  capacity  at 
the  existing  location.  Modernization  and  expansion  at  the  established  location 
may  be  rational;  and>  the  development  of  an  individual  company  at  a  particular 
location  may  thus  be  perpetuated. 

FACTORS    IN    EXPENDITURES    FOR    NEW    PLANTS    AND    EQUIPMENT 

The  number  of  producers  of  any  particular  steel  product  bears  a  rather  direct 
relationship  to  the  minimum  investment  required  to  become  such  a  producer. 
It  is  pertinent  to  inquire  first,  the  source  of  the  funds  for  such  capital  expenditures 
and  second  the  inducements  necessary  for  the  investment  of  these  funds. 

Source  of  Funds. — Funds  for  investment  in  npw  plants  and  equipment  may  be 
obtained  from  any  one  or  a  combination  of  the  following  sources:  (1)  Outside 
capital;  both  existing  companies  and  promoters  of  new  companies  may  borrbw 
through  the  medium  of  notes  and  bonds  or  sell  stock  to  obtain  funds  from  this 
source.  (2)  Accumulated  earnings;  the  availability  of  this  source  of  funds  over 
the  years  enabled  existing  companies  to  promote  and  keep  pace  with  the  upward 
trend  in- national  steel  consumption,  and  in  addition  helped  small  non-integrated 
and  semi-integrated  steel  companies  grow  into  large  integrated  units.  (3)  De- 
preciation and  other  reserves;  this  has  been  the  primary  source  of  funds  for  replace- 
ment and  modernization  programs. 

Incentives  for  Investment — Profit  Motive. — The  normal  incentive  for  investment 
is  prospective  profits.  This  may  cause  the  expansion  of  existing  companies;  the 
^development  of  non-integrated  and  semi-integrated  companies  into  integrated 
companies  being  a  case  in  point;  or  it  may  induce  new  companies  to  enter  the 
field  usually  as  non-integrated  or  semi-integrated  specialists.  The  formation  of 
a  new  integrated  steel  company,  except  by  merger,  would  not  be  likely  today 
since:  (1)  A  large  capital  investment  is  necessary.  (2)  The  technological  and 
organizational  difficulties  in  forming  such  a  company  are  great.  (3)  The  difficulty 
of  obtaining  an  immediate  market  for  the  output  of  such  a  new  company  would 
be  tremendous;  great  losses  in  early  years  would  therefore  seem  inevitable. 

Incentives  for  Investment — Obsolescence. — Obsolescence  has  been  an  important 
motive  for  capital  expenditures  by  the  steel  industry  in  recent  years.  This  has 
been  due  to:  (1)  New  production  techniques;  the  introduction  of  continuous  hot 
strip  mills  and  continuous  cold  reduction  proce.sses  has  brought  about  a  major 
technological  revolution  in  the  industry.  (2)  The  development  of  new  products; 
cold  reduced  sheets  and  cold  reduced  tin  plate  have  practically  displaced  the  hot 
rolled  products  in  major  markets.  In  order  to  remain  in  markets  demanding  the 
new  and  better  products,  companies  have  had  to  purchase  new  equipment  and 
construct  new  plants.  (3)  Shifts  in  demand;  e.  g.,  the  marked  increase  in  the 
demand  for  sheets,  strip,  tin  plate  and  other  steel  required  by  consumer  goods 
industries,  and  the  decline  until  very  recently  in  the  demand  for  rails,  plates  and 
structural  shapes.  This  shift  has  caused  expansion  of  existing  companies  both 
to  meet  the  new  demand  and  to  obtain  outlets  for  otherwise  unutilized  ingot 
capacities. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13903 

SIZE  AND  NUMBER  OF  PRODUCERS 

The  producers  of  the  bulk  of  tonnage  steel  are  large  in  size  and  relatively  few 
in  number,  which  is  a  natural  development  in  an  industry  requiring  great  capital 
investment  as  the  result  of  large  scale  equipment,  vertical  integration  and,  in 
certain  cases,  horizontal  integration.  Principal  producers  (including  subsidiaries) 
and  their  respective  percentages  of  total  ingot  capacity  for  the  year  1938  are 
indicated  in  the  following  table:  '^ 

Percentage  Distribution  of  Capacity  Among  Producers  of  Steel  Ingots  and  Steel  for 
Castings— 1938 

Percentage  of 
Total  I  Annual 

Name  of  Corporation  Capacity 

United  States  Steel  Corporation 35.  3- 

Bethlehem  Steel  Corporation 13.  7 

Republic  Steel  Corporation 8.  9 

Jones  &  Laughlin  Steel  Corporation 5.  0 

National  Steel  Corporation 4.  7 

Youngstown  Sheet  &  Tube  Company 4.  3 

Inland  Steel  Company 3.  9 

American  Rolhng  Mill  Company 3.  6 

Wheeling  Steel  Corporation 2.  4 

Other  smaller  companies .-      18.  2 

Total 100.  0 

1  This  total  does  not  include  those  companies  that  produce  steel  only  for  castings. 

However,  ingot  capacities  should  not  be  the  sole  criteria  of  the  size  and  number 
of  producers,  especially  in  the  consideration  of  markets  for  particular  products, 
since  the  number  of  companies  and  the  percentage  of  the  total  that  each  has 
capacity  to  produce  varies  with  individual  steel  products.  The  number  is  deter- 
mined by:  (1)  The  minimum  investment  required  in  equipment  to  produce  the 
product,  the  prospective  return  thereon,  and  the  relative  simplicity  of  the  opera- 
tion. The  investment  formerly  required  for  a  steel  mill  and  past  profit  margins 
must  be  considered  in  a  study  of  any  particular  company,  since  most  of  the 
present  producers  entered  the  market  under  conditions  different  from  those  which 
today  would  face  a  newcomer.  (2)  The  technological  history  of  the  product  and 
the  equipment  used  to  produce  it.  (3)  The  nature  of  the  demand  for  the  product; 
its  diversity  and  geographical  distribution.  (4)  The  historical  development  of 
the  producers. 

The  percentage  of  the  total  represented  by  the  capacity  of  any  individual  pro- 
ducer is  principally  a  reflection  of:  ''1)  The  historical  development  of  that  producer, 
particularly  with  reference  to  product  specialization;  (2)  The  technological  history 
of  the  product  and  the  equipment  used  to  produce  it;  (3)  The  producer's  location 
with  respect  to  demand. 

Under  the  influence  of  these  factors  there  are  distinct  variations  in  the  character 
and  total  number  of  producers  of  each  steel  product,  and  in  the  percentage  of 
total  capacity  possessed  by  each  producer  for  each  product,  and  in  the  geographical 
distribution  of  their  plants. 

CHANNELS  OF  DISTRIBUTION 

Approximately  80  percent  of  the  steel  produced  by  the  steel  industry  is  sold 
directly  to  consuming  industries  through  the  sales  organizations  of  the  producing 
companies  so  that  in  the  majority  of  cases  "sellers"  and  "producers"  are  inter- 
changeable terms  in  the  market  for  steel. 

Jobbers  and  Warehouses. — The  balance  of  the  steel  sold  passes  through  the  hands 
of  jobbers,  warehouses  and  other  distributors  which  are  essential  in  the  sale  of 
standardized  products  in  small  lots  to  widely  scattered  consumers,  or  where 
geographical  conditions  such  as  exist  on  the  West  Coast  make  this  form,  of  dis- 
tribution particularly  ecanomical. 

"  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute,  Iron  and  Steel  Works  Directory  of  the  United  States  and  Canada, 
1938,  pp.  401-402. 


13904  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Although  the  jobber  market  is  an  important  factor  in  the  distribution  of  steel, 
the  "influence  of  this  form  of  distribution  on  the  pricing  and  marketing  of  the 
majority  of  steel  products  is  negligible.  Jobber  outlets  are,  however,  important 
elements  in  the  marketing  of  galvanized  sheets',  concrete  reinforcing  bars,  standard 
pipe,  tubes,  and  merchant  wire  products. 

Importance  of  Outlets. — Maintenance  of  outlets  for  semi-finished  and  finished 
steel  is  important  for  most  members  of  the  steel  industry.  The  acquisitions  of 
such  outlets,  by  integrated  producers,  which  occur  from  time  to  time,  involve  a 
change  in  the  distribution  pattern  of  the  industry. 


The  supply  side  of  the  steel  market  from  a  long  term  viewpoint  is  marked  by 
these  characteristics:  (1)  The  areas  of  production  are  geographically  concentrated 
in  a  few  districts  because  of  location  of  raw  materials  and  transportation  costs. 
(2)  Large  size  equipment  and  vertical  integration  are  typical  of  the  industry; 
some  companies  are  also  horizontally  integrated,  while  a  number  of  semi-integrated 
or  non-integrated  companies  are  specialists  in  particular  products.  (3)  Large 
capital  investment  is  necessary;  however,  for  certain  products  the  investment 
necessary  to  become  a  producer  is  relatively  much  smaller  than  for  others,  and 
this  seems  to  be  an  important  controlling  factor  in  determining  the  number  of 
producers  of  a  given  product.  (4)  Generally  speaking,  producers  are  large  in 
size  and  few  in  number,  although  in  particular  cases  major  producers  of  specialty 
products  may  be  smaller  non-integrated  or  semi-integrated  units.  (5)  Investment 
in  new  plants  and  equipment  arises  both  in  response  to  prospective  profits  and 
as  a  result  of  obsolescence. 

In  contrast  with  many  types  of  markets  the  steel  market  is  one  not  easily  entered 
by  producers,  or  withdrawn  from,  once  enlry  has  been  accomplished.  The 
large  investment  required,  technological  and  organizational  difficulties,  and  the 
problem  of  obtaining  an  immediate  market  are  obstacles  to  entry.  The  non- 
recoverable  costs  that  must  be  sunk  in  a  steel  company  are  not  conducive  to  with- 
drawal if  there  is  an  opportunity  for  any,  return  in  excess  of  out-of-pocket  expenses. 

In  much  the  same  manner,  che  supply  side  of  the  steel  market  differs  from  other 
markets  in  that  productive  capacity  cannot  be  easily  adjusted  to  meet  changing 
market  conditions.  Once  capacity  is  installed,  it  is  inelastic .  and  cannot  be  re- 
moved except  by  scrapping,  which  ordinarily  does  not  appear  desirable  due  to 
the  large  investment  involved;  nor  can  capacity  be  easily  expanded  except  by 
heavy  capital  expenditures  requiring  a  considerable  time  interval. 

Characteristics  of  Cost  in  the  Industry 

"overhead"  or  "fixed"  costs 

There  are  certain  costs  in  the  steel  industry  which  are  approximately  the 
same  regardless  of  the  amount  of  steel  produced,  i*  These  costs  are  sometimes 
known  as  "overhead"  or  "fixed"  costs.  In  the  case  of  the  United  States  Steel 
Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  such  "fixed"  costs  are  composed  of  the  following 
elements  in  the  approximate  percentages  indicated: 


"  United  Staters  Steel  Corporation  &  Subsidiaries  Components  of  "Fixed"  Costs, 
under  1938  Conditions 

Item 

Approximate 
Percentage 

Interest 

4.1S6 

Pensions 

k^ 

vio 

Payroll              .  "::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::;: 

84.10 

Social  Security  Taxes 

1.37 

Goods  and  Services  Purchased  from  Others 

26.26 

Total.-  .                       .                            ...                     

100.00 

"  This  presumes  a  company  in  operation.    Complete  shutdown  naturally  would  decrease  these  costs 
sharply. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13905 

Other  steel  producers  may  have  dififerent  percentages  for  the  components  of 
their  "fixed"  costs  depending  on  the  degree  of  integration  and  their  capital  struc- 
ture. However,  regardless  of  their  composition,  such  costs  are  relatively  large 
for  major  producers  in  the  steel  industry,  and  with  low  operating  rates  are  a 
substantial  percentage  of  total  costs." 

"additional"  costs 

The  costs  over  and  above  "fixed"  costs  represent  the  "additional"  cost  inci- 
dental to  the  production  of  each  additional  ton  of  steel,  assuming  the  steel  mill 
is  already  in  operation.  Recent  studies  of  the  experience  of  the  United  States 
Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  over  the  past  ten  years  indicate  that  the 
addition  to  the  total  costs  arising  from  the  production  of  each  additional  ton  '" 
of  steel  is  the  same  regardless  of  the  operating  rate  at  which  the  additional  output 
is  obtained  as  long  as  the  other  factors  affecting  costs  remain  constant.  This 
phenomenon  of  constant  "additional"  costs  covers  an  observable  range  of  output 
which  extends  from  around  twenty  percent  of  capacity  to  slightly  beyond  ninety 
percent  of  the  physical  limit  of  output.  It  is  not  certain  that  this  relationship 
would  hold  true  as  the  physical  limit  of  capacity  is  reached  since  at  that  point  the 
equipment  may  become  overtaxed  and  for  various  reasons  operate  less  efficiently 
and  at  greater  cost.  Less  efficient  reserve  units  may  also  be  placed  in  service  to 
meet  the  peak  levels.  In  those  circumstances  the  additional  costs  incidental  to 
the  production  of  an  additional  unit  of  output  would  cease  to  be  constant  and  would 
probably  rise  sharply.  The  percentage  composition  of  these  costs  in  the  case  of 
the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  is  indicated  in  the  following 
table. 

United  States  Steel  Corporation  &  Subsidiaries  Components  of  "Additional" 
Costs,  under  1938  Conditions 

Approzlmat 
Percentage 

Taxes  (other  than  social  security  and  Federa,!  income) 2.  57 

Depreciation  and  Depletion 4.  25 

Payroll 52.22 

Social  Security  ^axes 2.  08 

Goods  and  Services  Purchased  from  Others 38.  88 

Totali. 100.00 

For  companies  less  integrated  than  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and 
its  subsidiaries  the  percentage  attributable  to  "Goods  and  Services  Purchased 
from  Others"  would  increase  and  the  percentage  of  other  components  decrease. 


AVERAGE    COSTS 

Since  the  average  cost  of  producing  a  given  ton  of  steal  is  the  sum  of  the  "ad- 
ditional" costs  plus  an  amount  equal  to  the  "fixed"  costs  divided  by  the  number 
of  units   produced,   this   "average"   cost  must  necessarily  be  higher  than  the 

"  See  the  following  table: 

United  States  Steel- Corporation  &  Suhsidiaries  Percentage  of  "Fixed"  to  Total  Costs  at  Various  Hates 
of  Operation,  under  19Sl  Conditions 


Operating  Rate 

Percentage  of 
"Fixed"  to 
Total  Costs 

Operating  Rate 

Percentage  of 
"Fixed"  to 
Total  Costs 

10 

57.2 
43.9 
35.8 
30.1 
26.0 

60 

22.9 

30 

:::::::::::::::::::::::::;:.. 

80 

18.5 

50  :::::::::::       :: 

100 

"  The  tons  mentioned  in  describing  the  cost  pattern  are  weighted  tons.  This  means  that  each  ton  of 
Rolled  and  Finished  steel  product  or  of  other  tonnage  product  which  is  of  a  type  whose  average  cost  is  less 
than  the  average  cost  of  all  Rolled  and  Finished  steel  products,  is  made  to  count  as  less  than  a  full  ton 
while  tons  of  products  of  a  class  which  is  on  the  average  more  costly  than  the  average  cost  of  Rolled  and 
Finished  .steel  products,  are  made  to  count  more  than  a  full  ton.  In  this  way  the  number  of  tons  of  all 
tonnage  products  shipped  has  been  converted  into  equivalent  tons  of  average-cost  Rolled  and  Finished 
steel  products.  The  result  is  that  total  costs  of  various  tonnages  shipped  are  made  comparable  where  they 
would  not  be  if  unweighted  tonnages  had  been  used. 


13906  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

"additional"  cost  for  nearly  the  whole  range  of  operations  almost  to  the  limits 
of  capacity.^' 

The  components  of  the  average  cost  of  producing  a  ton  of  steel  are,  to  a  certain 
degree,  largely  outside  the  control  of  steel  producers;  wage  rates  tend  to  be 
inflexible  and  lag  in  adjustment,  prices  paid  for  goods  and  services  are  often 
fixed  by  outside  agencies  as  they  are  in  the  case  of  railroad  rates,  interest  is 
determined  by  factors  in  the  money  market,  taxes  are  established  by  law,  and 
depreciation  and  depletion  charges  cannot  long  be  disregarded. 

The  Dynamics  of  the  Market  for  Steel 

COSTS    AND    demand 

The  inelasticity  of  the  total  demand  for  steel  and  the  aforementioned  charac- 
teristics of  cost  in  the  steel  industry  place  definite  limitations  on  the  financial 
ability  of  the  industry  to  increase  production  by  decreasing  prices.  Assuming 
that  each  1  percent  decrease  jn  price  would  increase  consumption  of  steel  1 
percent,  a  10  percent  decrease  in  the  average  level  of  steel  prices  prevailing  during 
1938  even  though  offset  by  a  10  percent  increase  in  the  quantity  of  steel  sold, 
would  have  increased  the  deficit  ^^  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  from 
$8,758,572.P0  to  $52,058,672.00.  This  estimate  is  most  conservative,  since  there 
is  every  indication  that  the  elasticity  of  the  demand  for  steel  is  not  as  great 
as  assumed  above. 

Despite  this  overall  price-volume-cost  relationship  in  the  industry,  the  potential 
elasticity  of  demand  for  the  product  of  an  individual  steel  company  and  the 
internal  problems  arising  within  individual  companies  from  this  characteristic 
cost  pattern  further  affect  the  market  for  steel. 

Except  in  periods  of  high  operations,  and  more  particularly  in  times  of  slack 
demand,  there  is  a  tendency  to  cut  prices  below  average  costs  so  long  as  the 
price  for  the  additional  unit  sold  is  above  the  "additional"  cost  necessary  to 
produfS-  tich  additional  ton  of  steel.  The  large  size-of  individual  orders  and  the 
potential  shiftability  of  buyers  of  steel  in  response  to  price  considerations  accen- 
tuate such  a  tendency,  particularly  wlren,  due  to  the  inelastic  nature  of  the  total 
denrtand  for  steel,  the  problem  fOr  the  individual  producer  is  to  obtain  a  share 
of  the  going  business.  Thus  it  is  that  in  periods  of  restricted  demand,  knowing 
that  anything  above  his  "additional"  costs  contributes  something  toward  "over- 
head" or  "fixed"  costs  which  must  be  met  in  any  event,  the  producer  will  cut 
prices  below  his  average  costs  if  he  feels  he  can  obtain  additional  business  for  his 
mills  thereby.  This  inherent  tendency  to  cut  prices,  however,  is  offset  to  Some 
extent  by  the  knowledge  that  competitors  will  meet  price  concessions  as  soon  as 
they  become  known. 

PSYCHOLOGICAL    FACTORS 

Buyers  and  sellers  of  steel  react  differently  at  various  stages  of  the  lousiness 
cycle;  this  is  natural  in  an  industry  marked  by  large  cyclical  fluctuations  in  the 
demand  for  its  products.  In  depression  the  tendency  toward  price  cutting  grows 
as  buyers  bargain  more  sharply  and  sellers  scramble  for  what  business  there  is 
in  an  effort  to  reduce  deficits  mounting  under  the  burden  of  "overhead"  or  "fixed" 
costs.  In  better  times  buyers  are  less  averse  to  paying  higher  prices,  and  sellers 
no  longer  under  the  goad  of  operating  losses  are  reluctant  to  make  price  conces- 
sions. Therefore,  in  part  at  least,  cyclical  fluctuations  in  steel  prices  are  attrib- 
utable to  changes  in  the  psychology  of  buyers  and  sellers. 

characteristic    patterns    of    ACTION    BY    SELLERS    IN    THE    MARKET    FOR    STEEL 

The  factors  mentioned  above  have  resulted  in  phenomena  that  reappear  each 
time  the  steel  industry  passes  through  a  full  cycle  in  demand.^'     In'a  jising  cycle 

"  In  the  case  of  United  States  'Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries,  the  average  cost  of  all  operations 
per  ton  of  steel  shipped,  under  1938  conditions,  would  be  $55.73,  plus  an  amount  equal  to  $182,100,000  Cthe 
total  "fixed"  costs)  divided  by  the  number  of  tons  produced. 

»  Deficit  after  deduction  of  bond  interest,  but  before  Federal  income  and  profit  taxes  and  exclusive  of 
non-operatinR  income  and  expense. 

"  The  pattern  outlined  has  perhaps  been  oversimplified  since  (1)  all  products  do  not  pass  through  each 
phase  of  the  cycle  simultaneously,  making  the  pattern  more  confused  than  it  appears  in  this  outline;  (2)  the 
existence  of  jobbers  and  distributors  complicates  the  situation  with  respect  to  certain  products;  (3)  in  addi- 
tion, the  homan  factor  is  unpredictable,  making  it  difficult  for  businessmen  always  to  rationalize  their 
actions  as  they  participate  in  a  highly  competitive  market. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13907 

as  demand  increases,  average  costs  in  the  industry  decrease  as  additional  unitfi 
are  produced,  but  these  decreases  are  usually  soon  offset  by  higher  raw  material 
prices,  and  increased  labor  and  other  costs.  In  addition,  as  already  indicated, 
the  psychology  of  the  buyers^  and  sellers  changes  and  the  industry  may  feel  that 
the  time  is  propitious  for  an  increase  in  prices,  not  only  to  cover  increased  costs, 
but  also  to  compensate  for  past  losses  and  to  accumulate  resources  for  possible 
future  periods  of  depression.  Quite  naturally,  however,  producers  of  steel  do 
not  care  to  take  the  risk  Oi  losiiig  their  share  of  business  by  an  increase  in  prices 
which  may  not  be  followed  by  their  competitors.^^  The  natural  result  is  that 
the  industry  is  inclined  to  wait  for  some  large  producer  to.  announce  higher 
prices.  This  natural  phenomenon  in  the  rising  cycle  is  sometimes  called  "price 
leadership".  So  long  as  the  term  is  used  to  describe  a  natural  phenomenon  re- 
sulting from  factors  inherent  in  the  industry  and  involving  no  collusion  or  other 
violation  of  the  anti-trust  laws,  there  is  little  objection  to  the  term. 

In  the  falling  cycle,  average  costs  increase  as  demand  and  production  decrease, 
accentuated  in  part  by  the  continuance  of  high  wages  which  have  a  tendency  to 
become  inflexible,  or  in  any  event  to  lag  in  their  adjustment  to  the  lower  level  of 
production.  In  the  early  stages  of  the  decline  in  demand,  the  industry,  aware  of 
the  inflexibility  of  the  total  demand  for  steel  and  faced  by  rising  average  costs  per 
unit  of  output,  naturally  is  averse  to  cutting  prices  when  the  prices  they  are 
getting  on  the  going  business  barely  cover  their  costs.  From  past  experience 
the  industry  is  aware  that  any  weakening  of  prices  leads  buyers  to  hold  off  pur- 
chasing in  the  expectation  that  prices  will  go  still  lower.  Then  too,  the  steel 
producer  may  be  optimistic  about  an  improvement  in  general  business  conditions 
in  the  near  future.  However,  sporadic  price  cutting  soon  breaks  out  spurred  by 
the  individual  producer's  hope  of  obtaining  an  additional  share  of  the  going 
business.  Concessions  soon  become  general  knowledge  in  the  trade;  and  while, 
for  a  period,  some  producers  may  not  care  to  compete  on  the  basis  of  these  con- 
cessions, eventually  all  producers  must  meet  competition  at  the  going  prices. 

The  Basing  Point  Method  of  Quoting  Delivered  Prices 

The  basing  point  method  of  quoting  delivered  prices  in  the  steel  industry  has 
developed  over  a  long  period  of  years  in  response  to  the  fundamental  economic 
factors  of  that  industry.  Two  authorities  on  the  economics  of  the  steel  industry 
succintly  point  to  the  basic  fallacy  in  the  reasoning  of  most  critics  of  this  pricing 
method  when  they  state  that  "Intelligent  appreciation  of  the  pricing  problem  in 
the  steel  industry  has  suffered  from  a  failure  of  most  commentators  to  distinguish 
between  the  basing  point  system  as  a  medium  or  mere  mechanism  for  the  trans- 
lation of  policy  into  action  and  the  economic  roots  of  that  primary  policy  itself."^' 

ECONOMIC  ROOTS  OF  THE  BASING  POINT  METHOD 

In  quoting  prices  manufacturers  of  steel  must  take  certain  basic  factors  into 
consideration:  (1)  The  cost  of  transportation  from  steel  mill  to  destination  may 
be  substantial  in  relation  to  the  value  of  steel  shipped.  Consumers  of  steel  are 
interested  in  the  cost  of  steel  at  the  place  where  they  use  it.  Therefore,  most 
consumers  want  to  know  the  lowest  delivered  price  at  which  they  may  purchase 
the  steel  they  require.'  (2)  Consumers  of  steel  are  located  in  different  parts  of 
the  country  and  although  more  steel  may  be  sold  in  some  sections  than  in  others, 
even  major  markets  for  the  same  steel  product  may  be  geographically  widespread. 

(3)  Producers  of  steel  must  locate  their  plants  at  points  where  raw  materials 
may  be  economically  assembled.  This  confines  major  steel  producing  centers  to 
a  few  geographical  areas.  Modern  steel  making  equipment  is  large  and  complex; 
it  requires  great  capital  investment  and  is  extremely  immobile  once  installed. 

(4)  To  insure  economical  and  reasonably  stable  operations,  steel  producers  must 
sell  large  quantities  of  steel  and  since  consumers  of  the  group  of  steel  products 
that  may  economically  be  produced  together  may  be  located  in  different  areas,  the 
producer  must  be  able  to   quote   prices  at   diversified  locations.     The   extent 

'*  Does  not  apply  where  all  capacity  of  a  pwrticular  product  is  booked  substantially  ahead. 
»  de  Chazeau  and  Stratton,  Economics  of  the  Iron  and  Steel  Industry,  by  Daugherty,  de  Chazeau  and 
Stratton,  p.  578  (McGraw-Hill  Book  Company,  1937). 


13908  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

to  which  he  may  economically  serve  diflFerent  consuming  areas  will  be  determined 
by  the  most  economical  combination  of  assembly  costs  of  raw  materials,  produc- 
tion costs  and  the  cost  of  delivering  finished  steel  to  important  markets.  (5) 
Producers  of  steel  have  large  "fixed"  costs,  which  must  be  met  regardless  of  the 
number  of  tons  produced  so  long  as  operations  are  continued.  Although  these 
producers  realize  that  the  total  quantity  of  steel  consumed  cannot  be  greatly 
influenced  by  reductions  in  steel  prices,  they  do  know  that  the  quotation  of  a 
delivered  price  only  slightly  below  other  quoted  delivered  prices  may  influence 
the  placement  of  substantial  orders  with  a  particular  producer.  Since  competition 
for  available  business  is  keen,  and  particularly  so  when  low  rates  of  operation 
make  the  "fixed"  costs  burdensome,  a  knowledge  of  the  level  at  which  competition 
must  be  met  in  quoting  prices  at  a  definite  location  is  valuable  in  preventing 
completely  disorganized  markets  that  might  prove  disastrous  to  the  industry. 

The  multiple  basing  point  method  of  quoting  delivered  steel  prices  is  a  simple 
pricing  medium  which  has  evolved  over  a  long  period  of  time  to  meet  the  peculiar 
characteristics  of  the  steel  industry.  It  is  an  open  price  method  of  quoting 
delivered  prices  at  diversified  locations.  Such  open  prices  are  similar  to  list 
prices  which  may  be  and  are  reduced  to  meet  competition.  As  a  pricing  medium 
it  permits  the  consumer  to  bargain  with  a  number  of  producers  for  both  steel 
and  service  at  the  lowest  possible  price  and  at  the  point  where  he  needs  it.  It 
serves  producers  by  permitting  them  to  compete  in  diversified  markets  to  obtain 
the  volume  and  even  flow  of  orders  necessary  to  economical  operations.  In 
essence,  it  provides  an  orderly  medium  by  means  of  which  consumers  and  pro- 
ducers of  steel  may  trade  to  their  mutual  benefit. 

Relation  of  Competition  to  Profits,  Capacity  and  Costs  of  Distribution 

Price  competition  is  necessary  in  any  industry  operating  in  a  capitalistic 
system.  Is  the  steel  industry  competitive?  Efforts  at  such  determination  too 
easily  lead  into  the  realms  of  economic  sophistry.  Criticism  and  defense  of 
competition  in  the  industry  should  not  be  based  on  abstract  criteria  which  fail 
to  take  into  account  the  fundamental  phenomena  involved;  it  should  be  based  on 
tangible  evidence. 

Edward  Chamberlin  in  his  notable  work,  "The  Theory  of  Monopolistic  Com- 
petition", demonstrates  that  evidence  of  imperfect  functioning  of  competition 
may  be  found  in  any  one,  or  a  combination  of  three,  undesirable  elements.^* 
The  first  is  excessive  profits  resulting  from  high  monopoly  prices.  The  second  is 
excessive  productive  capacity  induced  by  high  prices  which  encourage  the  entrance 
of  producers  into  the  market,  until  the  reduced  volume  of  each  lowers  profits  to 
the  minimum  level,  althoQgh  the  original  high  prices  remain.  The  third  is 
excessive  selling  costs  which  contribute  to  higher  prices  if  selling  costs  per  unit  are 
greater  than  the  decrease  in  production  costs  resulting  from  the  increased  volume 
of  production.  Selling  costs  are  simply  one  element  of  distribution  costs,  and 
Mr.  Chamberlin,  although  he  does  not  do  so,  could  apply  his  thesis  to  all  distri- 
bution costs  with  equal  force.  Assuming  that  excessive  profits,  excessive  capacity 
and/or  excessive  costs  of  distribution  are  criteria  of  the  lack  of  competition,  what 
is  the  position  of  the  steel  industry  with  respect  to  these  standards? 


Profits  in  the  steel  industry  are  not  excessive.  From  1919-1928  inclusive, 
the  average  return  on  investment  was  5.1  percent;  from  1929-1938  the  average 
rate  of  return  was  2.4  percent." 

A  study  based  on  a  composite  of  financial  statements  of  leading  companies  in 
their  respective  industries  illustrates  the  comparative  earnings  of  other  industries 
and  the  steel  industry  for  the  period  from  1929  to  1937  inclusive. 

"  Chamberlin,  Edward,  The  Theory  of  Monopolistic  Competition,  Chapters  V  and  VI,  Harvard  University 
Press,  1938. 

"  Steel  Facts,  August  1939,  No.  35.  p.  3.  Since  the  years,  components  and  sources  are  different  this  flRure 
naturally  does  not  agree  with  that  for  "Iron  and  Steel"  in  the  table  which  follows. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13909 

Ratio  of  Earnings  to  Net  Assets — 1939-37  Inclusive  (Earnings  Before  Interest  in 
Percent  of  Total  Assets  Less  Current  Liabilities)  Steel  Industry  Compared  With 
Other  Industries 

7*!aTninn  EdTTling 

Industry — Continued.  Ratio 

Motion  Pictures 5.  6 

Building  and  Real  Estate.  _^  5.  2 

Telephone  &  Telegraph .  5.  0 

Paper  and  Products 4.9 

Oil  Producing  and  Refining _.  4.8 

Metals  (Non- Ferrous)-  3.  8 

Rubber  &  Automobile  Tires.  3.  7 

Railroads  (Class  I) 3.  6 

Railroad  Equipment i .  _  3.  1 

Steel  and  Iron 2.  0 

Textiles  &  Apparel 1.5 

Coal 1.1 


Industry:  Ratio 

Tobacco  and  Products 12.  3 

■Vutomobiles  and  Trucks 11.7 

Household  Products 10.  6 

Office  Equipment 10.3 

Automobile  Accessories 10.  2 

Chemicals  and  Fertilizers 10.  1 

Leather  and  Shoes 9.3 

Retail  Trade 9.0 

Electrical  Elquipment  & 
Radio 7.  6 

Food  Products 7.6 

Public  Utilities 6.0 

Machinery  (Industrial  &  Ag- 
ricultural)..      5.7 

Sources:  Standard  Trade  and  Securities,  Standard  Statistics  Company,  Vol.  31  #20  Section  3  for  1927— 
1935.  Vol.  89  #15  Section  6  for  1936  and  1937. 

On  the  basis  of  these  figures  the  steel  industry  can  hardly  be  accused  of  excessive 
profits.     Are  these  low  profits  caused  by  excessive  capacity? 


Capacity  of  the  steel  industry  is  not  excessive.  Unused  or  idle  capacity  should 
not  be  confused  with  "excess"  capacity.  Past  experience  indicates  that  even  in 
periods  of  peak  demand  orders  are  not  distributed  among  products  in  such  a  way 
as  to  make  possible  fuU  utilization  of  all  facilities.  In  practice,  therefore,  opera- 
tions probably  would  never  be  maintained  at  100  percent  of  finished  steel  capacity 
because  of  lack  of  coordination  between  demand  and  capacity  for  various  products. 
Production  might,  therefore,  be  expected  to  run  five  or  ten  "percent,  or  even  more, 
below  capacity  at  the  peak  of  the  cycle. 

In  times  of  real  emergency,  or  under  the  tremendous  pressure  of  excessive  de- 
mands on  the  industry,  it  might  be  possible,  by  bringing  into  operation  obsolete 
facilities,  lengthening  the  work  week,  eliminating  holidays,  and  by  other  means, 
to  attain  an  operating  rate  in  excess  of  100  percent.  This  last  happened  in 
May  1929. 

True,  the  steel  industry  had  a  large  amount  of  unused  capacity  during  recent 
depression  years,  but  this  is  reasonable  and  to  be  expected  in  an  industry  with 
capacities  that  are  rigid  and  immobile  and  whose  rate  of  operations  is  so  controlled 
by  the  tremendous  cyclical  flu&tuations  in  the  demand  for  steel.  If  the  industry 
is  to  have  facilities  to  supply  the  peak  or  near-peak  demand,  it  must  have  idle 
capacity  during  the  periods  of  lower  demand.  An  industry  which,  in  the  partial 
recovery  of  1937,  produced  steel  ingots  for  three- successive  months  in  an  amount 
roughly  equivalent  to  the  average  monthly  capacity  for  the  industry  in  the  high 
production  year  of  192'9,  cannot  have  "excessive"  capacity  if  it  is  to  take  care  of 
the  demands  of  a  norndal  recovery  which  would  only  have  to  be  about  10  percent 
greater  than  the  peak  months  of  1937  to  utilize  the  present  full  capacity  of  the 
industry.  The  vital  importance  of  existing  capacity  is  emphasized  by  current 
conditions  which  make  it  imperative  for  the  steel  industry  to  produce  steel  in 
quantities  never  before  equaled  in  its  history.  Quite  conceivably,  with  any 
capacity  less  than  it  presently  possesses,  the  steel  industry  would  become  a  bottle- 
neck and  prevent  full  normal  recovery. 


13910 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


DISTRIBUTION    COSTS 

The  steel  industry  does  not  have  excessive  distribution  costs.  In  a  study  of 
distribution  costs  of  312  manufacturers  in  1931  ^^  "Iron  and  Steel  and  Their 
.  Products,"  a  very  broad  classification,  ranked  among  those  having  the  lowest 
distribution  costs.  The  steel  industry  proper  undoubtedly  had  even  lower  dis- 
tribution costs  than  those  companies  included  in  the  classification  "Iron  and 
Steel  and  Their  Products,"  if  the  records  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation 
and  its  subsidiaries  are  in  any  way  indicative  of  the  average  distribution  costs  for 
the  steel  industry. 

Selling  Expense. — The  major  elements  in  the  distribution  cost  study  referred 
to  are  "direct  selling  costs"  and  "advertising  and  promotion  costs."  These  two 
items  combined  represented  11  percent  of  net  sales  of  those  companies  reported  as 
component  manufacturers  of  "Iron  and  Steel  and  Their  Products";  in  1931,  the 
same  year  used  in  the  aforementioned  study,  direct  seUing  costs  and  advertising 
and  promotion  costs  were  3.1  percent  of  net  sales  for  the  United  States  Steel 
Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries.'^* 

Freight  Absorption. — An  element  more  or  less  peculiar  to  the  steel  industry  is 
the  amount  paid  by  a  steel  producer  for  the  transportation  of  steel  from  the  steel 
mill  to  the  customer  over  and  above  the  amount  of  the  freight  charge  included  in 
his  computation  of  the  delivered  price  under  the  basijig  point  method  of  quoting 
delivered  prices.  This  results  from  competition  in  the  steel  industry,  as  a  pro- 
ducer in  order  to  share  in  the  business  must  meet  the  delivered  price  of  a  com- 
petitor whose  steel  mill  is  nearer  freight-wise  to  the  customer.  This  is  sometimes 
called  "freight  absorption"  by  critics  of  the  basing  point  practice. 

A  broad  sampling  3"  of  shipments  for  the  month  of  February  1939  by  the 
American  Steel  &  Wire  Company,  Carnegie-Illinois  Steel  Corporation  and 
Tennessee  Coal,  Iron  and  Railroad  Company,  three  subsidiaries  of  the  United 
States  Steel  Corporation,  showed  average  "freight  absorption"  of  $1.99  per  ton 
equivalent  to  3.75  percent  of  the  net  sales  return  to  the  companies  on  these  ship- 
ments, and  3.6  percent  of  their  delivered  value  to  the  customer.^'  In  view  of 
the  fact  that  "freight  absorption"  plus  selling  expenses  and  advertising  and  pro- 
motion costs  for  the  steel  industry  are  less  than  just  the  selling  expenses  and 


'»  See  the  following  table: 


Distribution  Costs  of  31$  Manufacturer',  19SI 
[In  Per  Cent  of  Net  Sales] 


Product 

Percent 

Product 

Percent 

ConsuiULT  Products: 

Drugs  and  Toilet  articles 

48.8 

sail 

32.9 
32.2 

31.6 
31.0 
28.7 
27.1 
26.5 
24.7 
22.6 
21.7 
21.2 
18.9 

Consumer  Products— Continued. 
Agricultural  Supplies 

18  4 

Paints  &  Varnishes 

Tobacco  Products 

18  3 

Furniture 

Sporting  Goods 

18.2 

Heating  Equipment 

Radio  Equipment 

Industrial  Products: 

16.5 

Office  Equipment  &  Supplies... 

25.8 

23.7 

21.7 

20.4 

Chemicals  and  Allied  Products.. 

Electrical  Equipment- .  — 

Iron  and  Steel  &  Their  Products. 

Nonferrous  Metals 

Transportation  Equipment 

19.9 

Household  Appliances 

19  7 

Automotive 

19.0 

Clothing 

Home  Furnishings 

18.5 
15.5 

An  Analysis  of  the  Distribution  Costs  ofSli  Manufacturers,  As.sociation  of  National  Advertisers  and 
the  National  Association  of  Cost  Accountants,  New  York.  1933,  pp.  64,  106. 

"  Percentage  of  selling  expenses  and  advertising  and  promotion  costs  to  net  sales  for  the  United  States 
Steel  Corporation  for  1926  is  1.34%;  for  1027,  1.65%;  for  1928,  1.61%;  for  1929,  1.53%;  for  1930,  2.29%;  for  1931, 
3.07%,;  for  1932,  4.32%;  for  1933,  3.22%,;  for  1934,  3.32%;  for  1935,  2.79%;  for  1936,  2.27%,:  and  for  1937,  1.98%i 

"Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  Form  B.  Distribution  and  Pricing  of  Selected  Stee 
Products  for  month  of  February  1939. 

"  "Adjusted"  freight  absorption,  i.  e.,  the  above  mentioned  unadjusted  freight  absorption  less  basing 
point  price  differentials,  averaged  $1.33  per  ton,  equivalent  to  2.4%  of  the  delivered  value  for  the  above 
named  subsidiary  companies.  Data  based  on  Form  B  returns  for  the  55  steel  companies  reporting  show 
that  "unadjusted"  freight  absorption  for  those  companies  averaged  $1.77  per  ton,  or  3.2%  of  delivered 
value,  and  "adjusted"  freight  absorption  averaged  $1.16  per  ton,  or  2.1%  of  delivered  value.  (See  T.  N. 
E.  C.  Exhibit  No.  1409,  Charts  C27,  C28  and  C31.) 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13911 

advertising  and  promotion  costs  of  nearly  every  other  industry ,^2  it  canftot  be 
charged  that  distribution  costs  in  the  steel  industry  are  excessive. 

Since  excessive  profits,  capacity  and  distribution  costs  are  not  present  in  the 
steel  industry,  it  may  reasonably  be  concluded  that,  although  the  economic 
factors  in  the  steel  industry  are  such  that  it  cannot  survive  for  long  under  con- 
ditions of  cut-throat  competition,  it  is  sufficiently  competitive  to  be  free  of  the 
alleged  evils  of  lack  of  competition. 

Conclusion 


THE  FUNCTION  OF  THE  STEEL  INDUSTRY  IN  THE  NATIONAL  ECONOMY 

There  remains  one  question  of  vital  interest.  Does  the  steel  industry  perform 
its  proper  function  in  the  national  economy? 

As  a  Source  of  Raw  Material.— The  steel  industry  primarily  supplies  a  basic 
raw  material  for  the  production  of  other  goods  and  services.  Properly  to  per- 
form its  function  it  must  continuously  provide  material  meeting  the  exacting 
and  changing  demands  of  a  great  variety  of  industries  each  of  which  has  diversified 
requirements.  The  steel  industry  has  consistently  dbne  so,  as  is  clearly  evidenced 
by  the  industrial  growth  of  the  United  States.  The  steel  industry  has  developed 
new  products  and  improved  the  old  ones,  both  on  its  own  initiative  and  in  close 
cooperation  with  the  steel  consuming  industries.  In  fact,  if  it  were  not  for  the 
steel  industry,  many  of  the  major  improvements  in  products  of  other  industries 
would  not  have  been  possible.  For  example,  the  streamlined  all-steel  automobile 
would  have  been  impossible  to  construct  fifteen  years  ago  since  it  depends  upon 
the  deep  drawing  quahties  and  strength  of  the  modern  cold  rolled  sheets.  Due 
primarily  to  the  recently  introduced  cold  reduced  tin  plate  certain  fruits  and 
vegetables  are  now  available  throughout  the  year  as  canned  products.  Beer 
could  not  be  sold  in  cans  so  readily  if  the  steel  industry  had  not  developed  a 
special  type  of  tin  plate  which  can  withstand  internal  pressure.  New  stream- 
lined trains  use  high  tensile,  low  alloy  steels  and  stainless  steels  which  have  been 
developed  by  the  steel  industry.  Special  heat  treatments  have  been  discovered 
which,  when  applied  to  rails,  insure  better  and  longer  service. 

32  See  the  following  table: 

Selling  Expenses  and  Advertising  and  Promotion  Costs  of  SIB  Manufacturers  in  1931 

[In  Per  Cent  of  Net^Sales] 


Product 

Direct 
Selling 
Costs 

Advertis- 
ing &  Pro- 
motion 

Total 

Consumer  Products: 

11.3 
17.1 
14.8 
15.8 
21.3 
11.5 
10.9 
11.5 

12.8 
12.9 

15'l 

8.7 
9.1 
8.2 

1:5 

5.4 

14.6 
11.8 
10.0 

9.4 
10.6 
12.0 

9.0 
10.2 

8.8 

5.1 

18.4 
7.5 
6.1 
7.9 
3.2 
6.7 
6.0 
0.3 
6.2 
6.8 
4.0 
3.7 
2.9 
3.7 
2.2 
1.6 
8.2 
3.6 
5.3 

4.4 
3.0 
3.1 
2.5 

3;o 

2.0 
1.1 
1.7 
1.3 

29.7 

Paints  and  Varnishes 

2*  6 

Furniture 

20  9 

Heating  Equipment 

23  7 

Office  Equipment  and  Supplies 

24  5 

Confections  and  Bottled  Beverages 

18  2 

Petroleum  Products 

16.9 

Hbusohold  Appliances 

19.6 

Clothing 

15.3 

Shoes.... 

Hardware 

11  3 

9.8 

Tobacco  Products 

Sporting  Goods .. 

11.4 
12.0 

Radio  Equipment 

10  7 

Industrial  Products: 

11.9 

11.8 

Electrical  Equipment 

15  0 

Iron  and  Steel  and  Their  Products 

11  0 

Nonferrous  Metals 

11  3 

Transportation  Equipment 

10  5 

Textiles 

6  4 

An  Analysis  of  the  Distribution  Costs  of  SIS  Monvfactmers,  Associations  of  National  .\dvertiser 
and  the  National  Association  of  Cost  Accountants,  New  York,  1933,  pp.  64. 160. 


13912 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


To  produce  these  better  products  and  still  keep  costs  down,  the  steel  industry 
over  the  years  has  constantly  improved  its  equipment  and  has  developed  entirely 
new  equipment  such  as  the  continuous  sheet  and  strip  mills  which  so  recently 
revolutionized  the  industry.  It  cannot  be  said  that  the  steel  industry  has  been 
remiss  in  providing  better  materials  to  be  used  by  other  industries  to  make 
products  and  provide  services.  This  functioning  of  the  steel  industry  to  supply 
new  and  better  steels  is  particularly  germane  to  the  pricing  problem  since  quality 
improvements  are  usually  not  reflected  in  price  series.  In  addition,  many  types 
of  steel  which  are  in  actuality  new  products  may  be  known  by  the  names  orginally 
applied  to  the  products  they  replaced  and  as  a  result  the  new  products  and  the 
old  may  be  included  in  single  price  series  although  they  may  have  little  or  no 
homogeneity. 

As  a  Factor  in  Employment.' — Steel  prices  would  be  even  more  important  to 
the  national  economy  if  they  influenced  the  amount  of  goods  that  could  be  sold 
by  companies  for  which  the  steel  industry  is  a  source  of  supply,  and  so  affected 
the  rate  of  employment  in  those  industries.  This  study  has  indicated  that  the 
price  of  steel  is  of  negligible  importance  as  a  factor  in  the  demand  ♦'or  goods  made 
of  steel  because  of  the  small  perce  age  of  the  cost  of  the  steel  as  related  to  the 
cost  of  the  finished  product.  Steel  prices  have  little  effect  on  national  production 
or  employment.  This  is  not  to  imply  that  the  steel  industry  may  charge  any 
price  its  whim  or  fancy  may  dictate.  Competition  among  producers,  and  bargain- 
driving  purchasers  with  large  orders  to  place,  keeps  prices  at  levels  which  some- 
times do  not  even  cover  costs. 

It  has  been  charged  by  some  that  steel  prices  have  remained  firm  in  the  face 
of  falling  demand,  and  as  a  direct  result  production  and  pay  rolls  have  declined 
drastically.  If  the  implications  of  this  charge  could  be  sustained  it  would  be  a 
serious  indictment.  But  they  cannot  be  sustained.  This  study  has  shown  that 
the  demand  for  steel  is  derived  from  the  demand  for  goods  made  of  steel.  This 
demand  depends  in  turn  on  such  factors  as  the  level  of  national  income  and  con- 
fidence that  in  the  future  there  will  be  opportunity  for  the  profitable  use  of  addi- 
tional durable  goods.  The  total  demand  for  steel  is  inelastic;  that  is,  the  total 
quantity  of  steel  bought  from  t'  e  industry  would  not  be  substantially  different 
at  any  particular  time  if  the  pric  :  were  higher  or  lower.  The  steel  industry  must 
have  orders  on  hand  before  it  ca  ^  produce;  steel  is  made  to  exacting  specifications 
for  particular  uses;  the  very  buikiness  of  such  steel  items  as  might  be  made  in 
anticipation  of  future  demand  prevents  their  heavy  production  for  inventory. 
If  there  is  lack  of  confidence  in  the  future  and  declining  national  income,  produc- 
tion and  consequently  hours  of  employment,  will  decrease  despite  all  efforts  of 
steel  producers.  Only  confidence  in  the  future  and  actual  or  anticipated  increase 
in  national  income  can  create  production  and.  resultant  employment  in  the  steel 
industry. 

Despite"  the  negligible  influence  of  price  on  demand  for  steel,  and  waiving  the 
fact  that  the  composite  published  price  of  steel  is  more  flexible  than  critics  often 
suppose,  and  the  further  fact  that  net  yields  received  by  the  industry  are  more 
flexible  than  indicated  by  published  figures,^^  what  adjustments  would  have  to 
be  made  if  steel  prices  were  cut  appreciably?  Since  substantial  "fixed"  costs 
must  be"  met  regardless  of  the  amount  of  steel  produced,  prices  cannot  be  out  of 
line  with  total  costs  over  any  considerable  period. 

What  costs  could  be  adjusted  if  prices  were  substantially  reduced  when  the  in- 
dustry was  operating  at  50  percent  of  capacity?  Based  on  cost  data  of  the 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  previously  discussed,  pay- 
rolls would  be  approximately  50  percent  of  total  costs  at  that  rate  of  operation; 
goods  and  services  purchased  from  others,  34  percent;  taxes  and  depreciation  and 


the  following  table: 


Indexes  of  Prices 
[1926=100] 


Year 

Composite 

Iron  Age 

Prices 

U.  S.  R.  C. 
Mill  Net 
Yields 

Year 

Composite 

Iron  Age 

Prices 

V.  S.  S.  C. 
Mill  Net 
Yields 

100.0 
95.1 
93.5 
95.4 
88.5 
84.5 
82.1 

100.0 
,  _      96.5 
9?  3 
94.5 
87.9 
81.3 
78.8 

1933 -. 

81.2 
87.8 
88.9 
89.7 
106.4 
103.4 

76.7 

1927 

1934.... 

89.1 

1928 

1935 

90.9 

1928    . 

1936 

88.6 

1930    . 

1937 

99.6 

1931. 

1938 

99.8 

1932    . 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13913 

depletion  about  7  percent  each;  and  the  remaining  2  percent  of  total  costs  would 
represent  interest  to  bondholders  and  pensions  to  retired  workers.  There  is  no 
getting  away  from  taxes;  they  must  be  paid.  Depreciation  and  depletion  charges 
could  be  overlooked  for  short  periods,  but  not  for  long.  If  interest  were  not 
paid,  the  Company  would  be  forced  into  bankruptcy.  The  remaining  84  percent 
of  total  costs  represents  payrolls  and  goods  and  services  purchased  from  others. 
Goods  and  services  purchased  from  others  perhaps  could  be  obtained  at  lower 
prices  by  sharp  bargaining  where  the  prices  are  not  fixed  by  law  as  they  are  in  the 
case  of  railroad  rates.  Payrolls  remain.  They  are  50  percent  of  total  costs. 
There  is  very  little  doubt  that  any  appreciable  cut  in  steel  prices  over  the  long 
run  would  have  to  be  met  by  reducing  wage  rates. 

As  a  Factor  in  the  Growth  of  the  Nation. — This  study  has  discussed  the  productive 
capacity  of  the, steel  industry  and  indicated  the  reasons  why  unused  capacity  may 
be  present  in  certain  periods,  but  excess  capacity,  in  the  sense  that  it  is  not 
necessary  to  the  economic  well-being  of  the  industry  and  of  the  nation,  is  absent. 
It  has  been  shown  that  assembly  costs  of  raw  materials,  the  geographical  location 
of  markets  for  products  that  may  be  economically  produced  together,  the  im- 
mobility of  steel-making  equipment,  the  huge  investment  required  therein,  and 
the  historical  development  of  individual  companies  are  more  important  than  the 
pricing  method  in  accounting  for  the  existence  of  more  capacity  in  certain  dis- 
tricts than  local  consumption  might  seem  to  dictate.  It  has  been  pointed  out 
that  steel-making  capacity  has  developed  in  every  area  where  raw  material  as- 
sembly costs,  costs  of  production  and  nearness  to  consuming  markets  have  been 
conducive  to  such  development.  On  these  bases  it  cannot  be  contended  that  the 
price  structure  of  the  steel  industry  has  been  instrumental  in  the  preservation  of 
uneconomic  capacity  nor  in  the  prevention  of  the  expansion  of  economic  capacity. 

In  brief,  the  steel  industry  has  efficiently  performed  its  function  in  the  national 
economy,  has  materially  assisted  in  the  development  of  this  country,  and  has 
ever  been  prepared  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  nation  in  each  forward  surge  of 
prosperity  as  well  as  in  times  of  national  emergency. 


Exhibit  No.  1411 
A  STATISTICAL  ANALYSIS  OF  THE  DEMAND  FOR  STEEL,  1919-1938 

This  is  an  analysis  prepared  by  the  Special  Economic  Research  Section  of 
United  States  Steel  Corporation,  composed  of  Messrs.  Edward  T.  Dickinson, 
Jr.,  Ernest  M.  Doblin,  H.  Gregg  Lewis,  Jacob  L.  Mosak,  Mandal  R.  Segal, 
Dwight  B.  Yntema  and  Miss  Marion  W.  Worthing.  The  work  of  this  group 
was  under  the  supervision  of  Theodore  O.  Yntema,  Professor  of  Statistics, 
University  of  Chicago.  This  analysis  was  written  by  H.  Gregg  Lewis  who  had 
the  benefit  of  suggestions  from  other  members  of  the  staff.  It  is  issued  by  United 
States  Steel  Corporation. 

November  1,  1939. 

CONTENTS 

I.  statement  of  the  Problem 
II.  Summary  of  Conclusions 

III.  Some  General  Considerations  on  the  Demand  for  Steel 

IV.  Method  of  Analysis 

V.  Factors  Which  Might  Be  Expected  to  Influence  the  Quantity  of  Steel  Sold 
VI.  The  Period  Studied 
VII.  The  Demand  Relation  Hypothesis 
VIII.  The  Statistical  Findings 

I.  Statement  of  the  Problem 

This  analysis,!  undertakes  to  measure  the  importance  of  the  level  of  steel 
prices  in  determining  the  quantity  of  steel  ^  sold.  More  specifically  the  question 
to  be  considered  in  this  study  is: 

If  the  average  level  of  steel  prices  in  any  year  had  been  higher    . 
or  lower  than  it  actually  was  by  a  certain  percentage,  but  every- 

.'  No  attempt  will  be  made  In  this  paper  to  summarize  or  criticize  previous  statistical  studies  of  the  demand 
for  steel,  except  as  this  study  does  so  by  implication.  However,  the  following  reports  should  be  consulted 
in  connection  with  this  paper:  Henry  L.  Moore,  Economic  Cycles:  Their  Law  and  Cause  (New  York,  1914); 
Roswell  H.  Whitman,  "Statistical  Investigations  in  the  Demand  for  Ironand  Steel",  Ph.  D.  dissertation. 
University  of  Chicago,  1933;  National  Resources  Committee,  Industrial  Committee,  Patterns  of  Resource 
Vne  (Preliminary  Edition  for  Technical  Criticism);  (Washington,  1939),  pp.  63,  65,  128-129,  131-132. 

'  Throughout  this  paper  the  term  steel  should  be  understood  to  include  only  those  products  sold  by  the 
steel  production  industry— i.  e.,  what  is  generally  understood  as  the  steel-works  and  rolling  mills  industry— 
to  consumers  outside  that  industry.  The  term  pTodndf-madefrom-steel  includes  all  products  into  which 
steel  so  defined  enters  as  a  raw  material  of  production. 


13914  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

thing  else  had  been  the  same,'  by  what  percentage  and  in  what 
direction  would  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  in  that  year  have 
changed?  In  other  words,  what  is  the  price  elasticity  of  demand 
for  steelf 

II.    Summary  ofConclusions 

The  analysis  of  the  following  pages  indicates  that  in  the  period  1919  to  1938, 
year  to  year  fluctuations  in  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  are  accounted  for  in  major 
part  by  changes  in  economic  factors  other  than  the  price  of  steel.  Only  a  very 
small  part  of  tlie  changes  in  steel  sales  can  be  attributed  to  steel  price  changes.* 

The  statistical  analysis  indicates,  although  not  entirely  conclusively,  that  the 
demand  for  steel  is  very  inelastic,  i.e.,  that  changes  in  the  level  of  steel  prices 
(other  conditions  of  steel  demand  remaining  the  same)  cause  much  smaller  per- 
centage changes  in  the  opposite  direction  in  the  quantity  of  steel  sold.'  The 
best  estimate  of  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  indicated  by  this  analysis  is 
approximately  .3  or  .4. 

This  means  that  very  large  reductions  in  price  would  be  necessary  to  effect 
significant  increases  in  the  volume  of  sales.  Such  price  reductions  would  decrease 
the  gross  income  of  the  steel  producers,  while  at  the  same  time  increasing  their 
total  costs  of  production. 

The  major  factors  affecting  the  demand  for  steel,  such  as  consumers'  income, 
industrial  profits  and  business  anticipations,  seldom  remain  constant.  In  the 
period  1919-1938  fluctuations  in  these  and  other  factors  were  of  such  great  mag- 
nitude and  importance  that  it  would  have  been  impractical  to  attempt  to  maintain 
the  level  of  steel  production  by  compensatory  changes  in  steel  prices. 

III.  Some  General  Considerations  on  the  Demand  for. Steel 

It  may  seem  that  the  economic  and  statistical  problems  involved  in  an  econo- 
metric analysis  of  the  demand  for  steel  are  simple.  The  demand  for  no  other 
product,  however,  is  more  complex,  or  presents  greater  analytical  problems. 

A.  steel  is  not  a  homogeneous  commodity 

The  steel  industry  is  generally  pictured  as  a  mass-production  industry,  selling 
only  a  few  types  of  steel  products,  a  pound  of  which  is  like  every  other  pound  of 
the  same  type  in  physico-chemical  composition,  degree  of  processing  or  fabrication, 
general  shape  and  dimensions. 

Actually,  the  steel  industry  produces  thousands  of  steel  products,  most  of  which 
are  practically  made-to-order  to  the  chemical,  physical,  shape,  and  dimension 
specifications  of  each  buyer.'  And  each  of  the  many  steel  products  has  its  own 
price. 

It  ii  obvious  that  a  demand  analysis  cannot  reasonably  be  made  for  each  of 
these  innumerable  steel  products.  Thus,  one  is  confronted  at  the  outset  with 
the  problem  of  combining  all  steel  products  into  a  composite  who^e  quantity  and 
price  can  be  measured.' 

B.  steel  is  a  raw  material,  a  producers',  not  a  consumers',  good 

Steel  as  it  is  sold  by  the  steel  producers  usually  is  not  a  finished  product  ready 
for  use  (consumption)  by  the  ultimate  consuming  public.  It  is  a  raw  material 
used  by  its  buyers,  along  with  labor,  machines,  and  other  raw  materials  in  the 
production  of  products-made-from-steel.* 

Thus  the  demand  for  steel  does  not  depend  solely  and  directly  upon  t^e  con- 
ditions determining  consumers'  purchases — but  is  indirectly  derived  from  the 
conditions  affecting  the  output  of  products-made-from-steel. 

3  Except  to  the  extent  that  changes  in  other  factors  averting  the  demand  for  steel  are  caused  by  the  change 
in  the  level  of  steel  prices. 

<  See  Section  VIII,  pp.  25-28.  In  the  years  1919-1938  chanpe,s  in  the  level  of  steel  prices  were  generally 
of  smaller  relative  magnitude  than  changes  in  other  factors  afTecting  the  demand  for  steel.  It  is  obvious 
that  large  price  changes  have  greater  effects  than  small  price  changes.  But  the  effects  of  the  changes  in 
steel  prices  were  so  smalt  in  the  period  studied  as  to  afford  no  basis  for  the  inference  that  considerably 
greater  price  changes  would  have  been  more  than  a  minor  influence  in  determining  the  volume  of  steel 
produced  and  sold. 

»  See  Section  VIII,  pp.  27-28. 

»  See,  for  example,  the  list  of  steel  products  in  the  Census  of  Manufacturers,  1929  (United  States  Depart- 
raont  of  Commerce,  Bureau  of  the  Census,  1933T;  pp.  953-958.  Each  type  listed  is  composed  of  many  differ- 
pnt  steel  pro^iucts  sharing  only  the  common  characteristic  s  of  the  type.  See  also  the  list  of  steel  products 
for  which  prices  are  published  weelvly  in  the  steel  trade  journal.  The  Iron  Age. 

7  See  pp.  4 1  -44  for  a  further  discussion  of  this  problem. 

»  See  p.  1,  footnote  2  above  for  a  definition  of  steel  and  prcducts-made-from-steel. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13915 

This  complicates  the  analysis  because  the  amount  of  steel  sold  to  a  orodnopr 
of  products-made-from-steel  depends  largely  on:  producer 

(1)  His  current  and  expected  output  of  products-made-from-steel     This  is 
m  turn  dependent  upon  an  interrelation  of'^numerous  factors^uch  as- 

fhi''i^^'%?>!''"'''l*  Tk"^  expected  costs  of  production,  including  not  only 
the  cost  of  the  steel  he  uses,  but  many  other  costs  as  well 

prc^dU'ttm^tSslee™"'"'"*'  °'  *^^  ""^'^^*  ^"  "^^^^  ^«  ««^  ^- 

wii?depend  upon  *  ''^  '*^''  ^^  T'  ^^^  ""^*  °^  Product-made-from.steel,  which 

of  5LT  ^ni'^'^'^K  °.-?^i''^'  characteristics  of  his  product-made-from-steel: 

(b)Th\  price  oTsfee^"  "^''"''''  ^^^  ""^  ^^'  production  methods.    ' 

(c)  The  cost  of  using  substitutes  for  steel.'" 

C.    STEEL    is    USED    IN    THE    PRODUCTION    OF    MANY    WIDELY    DIFFERING    KINDS    OF 
PRODUCTS-MADE-FROM-STEEL 

That  products-made-from-steel  are  almost  innumerable  and  widelv  diverse  in 
kind  IS  a  point  that  need  not  be  labored.  One  has  only  to  observe 'the  number 
of  products-made-from-steel  which  enter  into  everyday  activity 
nf  ill  tl^r.?  r"'  ^'"^,^^^  relations  among  the  factors,  determining  the  outputs 
of  all  types  of  products-made-from-steel  were  more  or  less  identical:  the  diversHv 
of  products-made-from-steel  would  present  no  great  analytical  difficStiesTndP 
from'si^eV  nterTT'  '^^  '''''■  I^^  ^^vious.  ho'wever,  tha't  since  proSute-m\l^^ 
,v™;-  enter  into  so  many  diflfenng  aspects  of  economic  activity,  the  deter- 
minations of  their  outputs  must  also  differ  greatly.  The  way  in  which  the  outmft 
«ndl3?''''  f  determined  is.certainly  much  different  ?rSiat  for  Lto^^^^^^^ 
and  that  for  automobiles  different  from  that  for  battleships  auiomoDiies, 

It  IS  clearly  an  impossible  task  to  make  an  analysis  of  the  output  of  everv  tvne 
n  P^«duct-made-from-steel.H  Thus  again  we.  have  the  index  number  probleS 
of  combining  the  many  products-made-from-steel,  the  factors  which  dete?miS 
nu^mVe?KroiL'^corpSs:^i  ^^^^  ^'^'  ^^  ^^^  ^  -^P"*  int^ot  rfalrCS 

D.    STEEL    IS    LARGELY    USED    IN    THE    PRODUCTION    OF    DURABLE    GOODS  '^ 

onl^rZ.f!^'"^''^^'^'  e^o^o^icf  to  observe  that  goods  are  valuable-that  is,  can 
command  a  pnce  on  the  market-only  for  the  services  thev  provide."  Thus  the 
demand  for  goods  essentially  is  derived  from  the  demand 'fo?  the  services  of  thl 

The  pecuhar  characteristic  of  durable  goods  is  that  they  can  provide  services 
over  a  long  period  of  time.  Once  a  stock  of  durable  goods  has  been  built  u^fj 
minishi^iflnr?'^  ''°"?°^^'  societies-it  is  possible  to  obtain  an  atoostS 
yZuZl  r  t^^'^^'T'  f'-o'"  them  for  u  long  period  of  time  without  the  production 
JJJI^  ,  "^l'  '^''"'^i-  r?"«^«P<'««.  that  is,  may  go  on  without  a  correspond- 
wlfenTf  "!«  . °^  new  durable  goods.  New  durable  goods  wiU  be  produced  only 
when  It  IS  economically  desirable  to  replace  "worn  out"  durable  goods  Tnd  to 

124491 — 41— pt.  26 22 


13916       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

3nlarge  the  stock  of  durable  goods.  Thus  it  is  obvious  that  the  production  of 
new  durable  goods  tends  to  be  largely  dissociated  from  the  consumption  of  the 
services  of  the  stock  of  durable  goods.  For  the  same  reason,  the  amplitude  of 
cyclical  fluctuations  in  the  production  of  new  durable  goods  will  tend  to  be  greater 
than  the  variations  in  ^he  consumption  of  durable  goods  and  in  the  production 
and  consumption  of  perishable  goods.  Since  the  demand  for  steel  is  derived 
largely  from  the  production  of  new  durable  goods,  it  follows  that  there  will  be 
great  cyclical  fluctuations  in  the  quantity  of  steel  sold. 

Upon  what  factors  does  the  demand  for  new  durable  goods  depend?  Inasmuch 
as  the  conditions  of  demand  for  prodvcers'  durable  goods  differ  in  some  respects 
from  those  for  consumers'  durable  goods,  each  of  these  types  will  be  discussed 
separately. 

(1)  Factors  Affecting  the  Demand  for  New  Producers'  Durable  Goods. — Broadly 
speaking,  a  producer  will  not. purchase  a  new  durable  producers'  good  unless  he 
can  reasonably  expect  that  the  return  attributable  to  the  new  good  over  its  "life 
span"  will  be  sufficient  to  cover  all  the  costs  (including  a  reasonable  profit)  attrib- 
utable to  the  purchase  and  use  of  the  good.  That  is,  the  purchase  must  be 
expected  to  be  a  profitable  one. 

Among  the  most  important  factors  determining  the  profitability  of  such  pur- 
chases are: 

(a)  The  current  demand  and  the  future  demand  expected  by  the  producer 
for  his  output  of  goods  and  services. 

(b)  His  present  stock  (number  of  units,  age  and  eflSciency  of  the  units,  and 
expected  life  span  of  the  stock)  of  durable  goods. 

(c)  The  purchase  price  of  the  new  durable  good,   including  financing 
charges. 

(d)  The  expected  life  span  and  efficiency  of  the  new  durable  good.     That 
is,  the  expected  life  "capacity"  of  the  new  durable  good. 

(e)  The  "costs  of  using"  the  good — i.  e.,  the  labor,  material,  managerial 
costs,  etc.,  involved  in  the  use  of  the  good. 

(f)  The  expected  sale  price  per  unit  of  the  output  of  the  good. 

(g)  The  current  and  anticipated  costs  of  (including  the  "costs  of  using") 
substitutes,  such  as  labor,  for  the  new  durable  goods. 

(2)  Factors  Affecting  the  Demand  for  Consumers'  Durable  Qoods. — The  most 
important  factors  affecting  the  demand  for  consumers'  durable  goods  are:  " 

(a)  The  current  and  anticipated  amount  of  consumers'  disposable  cash 
income. 

(b)  The  distribution  of  such  income  among  economic  classes. 

(c)  The  size  (number  of  units,  age  distribution,  efficiency,  and  expected 
life  span)  of  the  stock  of  consumers'  durable  goods. 

Cd)  The  present  and  anticipated  price  of  the  new  durable  good. 

(e)  The  costs  of  operating  (including  maintenance)  the  new  durable  good 

(f)  The  cost  of  obtaining  competing  consumer  services,   including  the 
"costs  of  living." 

(g)  Consumers'  tastes. 

It  is  apparent  that  the  demand  for  new  durable  goods  is  determined  by  a  complex 
composite  of  factors.  Moreover,  not  all  of  the  factors  are  directly  measurable. 
Since  the  complete  "fund  of  services  stored"  in  durable  goods  can  be  used  up 
(consumed)  only  over  a  more  or  less  long  pe'rod  of  time,  anticipations  are  of  para- 
mount importance  in  determining  the  output  of  new  durable  goods.  Thus  there 
arises  the  problem  of  "measuring"  changes  in  producers'  and  consumers'  states  of 
mind." 

There  is  a  further  and  very  important  analytical  problem.  Since  the  amount 
of  any  commodity  bought  and  sold  depends  not  only  on  its  price  but  also  on  a 
complex  set  of  other  factors,  an  analysis  which  attempts  to  isolate  the  influence  of 
price  is  more  difficult  when  the  other  factors  are  numerous,  important,  and  subject 
to  great  or  rapid  changes.  If,  for  example,  as  is  the  case  for  certain  staple  agri- 
cultural commodities,  only  a  few  factors  other  than  price  tend  to  be  important  in 
determining  the  quantity  sold,  and  tend  also  to  follow  a  slow  and  regular  routine 
of  change,  the  problem  of  isolating  the  effect  of  price  is  simplified.  In  the  case  of 
durable  products-made-from-steel,  however,  factors  other  than  price  are  numerous, 
exert  very  important  effects,  and  tend  to  have  large  and  irregular  variations. 

'•  See  Roos  and  von  SzeliskI,  op.  cit..  for  an  analysis  of  the  demanil  for  automohllcs. 

"  Inasmuch  as  current  anticipations  depend  for  the  most  part  on  the  recent  and  current  behavior  of  factors 
which  in  many  cases  can  be  measured,  an  approximate  measure  of  anticipations  can  often  be  obtained  from 
study  of  the  measurable  factors.    See,  for  example,  pp.  22-23. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13917 

Thus  the  problem  of  isolating  the  effect  of  the  price  of  steel  on  the  quantity  of 
steel  sold  is  exceedingly  difficult. '^ 

E.   STEEL  IS  DURABLE  AND  CAN  BE  STORED 

Since  steel  itself  is  durable,  it  may  be  kept  in  stock  for  fairly  long  periods  without 
serious  physical  deterioration."  Thus,  purchasers  of  steel  may  currently  buy 
more  steel  than  they  require  for  current  (or  anticipated  near  future)  consumption, 
building  up  a  stock  of  steel  for  future  production  requirements.  Conversely, 
the  building  up  of  such  a  stock  in  the  past  enables  a  steel  purchaser  currently  to 
buy  less  steel  than  he  consumes,  the  balance  of  such  consumption  coming  from 
depletion  of  his  steel  inventories.  If  changes  in  the  size  of  steel  inventories  in  the 
hands  of  consumers  (buyers)  tend'  to  be  large,  then  it  is  obvious  that  the  size  of 
such  inventories  is  an  important  factor  influencing  the  sales  of  steel  producers. 

The  size  of  steel  inventories  in  the  hands  of  consumers  ^^  will  depend  for  the 
most  part  on: 

(1)  Buyers'  anticipations  as  to  future  prices  of  steel. 

(2)  Their  expected  production  requirements,  which  will  depend  largely  on 
their  expected  sales  of  products-made-from-steel. 

(3)  The  expected  length  of  time  it  will  take  to  get  delivery  from  steel 
producers  on  future  orders  of  steel. 

(4)  The  cost  of  carrying  such  inventories. 

If  the  steel  buyer  expects  that  prices  of  steel  shortly  will  be  higher,  or  that 
near-capacity  operations  of  steel  producers  may  delay  delivery  on  his  orders  at  a 
time  when  his  steel  requirements  will  be  high,  he  may  currently  buy  more  than  he 
needs  for  current  consumption,  stocking  steel  as  protection  against  future  higher 
prices  or  delivery  delay.  On  the  other  hand,  if  his  steel  requirements  turn  out 
to  be  smaller  than  expected,  he  may  find  himself  with  unnecessarily  large  inven- 
tories of  steel  on  hand.  Thus  he  may  consume  from  stock,  curtailing  his  buying 
below  his  current  production  requirements. 

However,  such  changes  in  inventories,  which  are  largely  speculative,  for  the  most 
part  exert  only  a  short  run  effect  on  steel  buying.  The  effect  usually  is  a  short 
run  shift  in  the  time  of  the  actual  purchases,  Tvithout  changing  the  total  amount 
of  steel  bought  over  a  one  or  two  year  period  from  what  it  otherwise  would  have 
been. 

The  reasons  for  this  are: 

(a)  Inventories  of  steel  cannot  be  reduced  below  a  certain  minimum 
(which  depends  largely  on  the  level  of  the  producers'  operations)  without 
serious  inconvenience.  This  is  especially  true  when  there  is  danger  of  delay 
in  delivery  of  orders  of  steel. 

(b)  On  the  other  hand,  the  cost  of  carrying  inventories  and  the  risks  in- 
volved tend  to  set  an  upper  limit  to  their  size.  The  larger  the  inventories, 
the  higher  is  the  carrying  expense,  and  the  further  into  the  future  must  the 
user  anticipate  prices  of  steel  and  his  own  production  requirements.  Such 
anticipations  become  more  risky  as  they  extend  longer  into  the  future.  The 
situation  seldom  arises  when  the  coets  of  carrying  are  low  enough,  and  the 
future  certain  enough  to  justify  changing  inventories  by  more  than  a  few 
months'  production  requirements. 

'This  is  not  to  say,  however,  that  year-to-year  fluctuations  in  steel  inventories 
are  unimportant  in  explaining  year-to-year  changes  in  steel  buying.  In  periods 
of  rapid  change  in  business  activity  and  business  outlook — such  as  the  period  from 
the  middle  of  1936  to  the  middle  of  1938 — changes  in  the  size  of  inventories  may  be 
very  important. 

Thus  in  analyzing  the  demand  for  steel  it  is  necessary  to  include  as  a  factor  net 
changes  in  steel  inventories  in  the  hands  of  steel  buyers,  or  in  the  absence  of  such 
data,  the  factors  upon  which  the  size  of  steel  inventories  depends. 

"  An  excellant  discussion  of  the  problem  of  isolating  the  effect  of  price  in  the  derivation  of  quantity-price 
demand  relations  is  contained  in  Henry  Schultz,  Theory  and  Measurement  of  Demand  (Chicago,  1938), 
pp.  61-104. 

"  There  are,  of  course,  exceptions  to  this  statement;  for  example,  cold  reduced  auto  sheets  should  be  used 
promptly. 

so  This  section  deals  only  with  changes  in  inventories  of  steel  in  the  hands  of  consumers.  However,  steel 
producers  themselves  may  keep  stocks  of  steel.  Inasmuch  as  the  largest  part  of  the  steel  produced  is  made 
to  order  to  the  buyer's  specification,  changes  in  inventories  of  finished  steel  in  the  hands  of  producers  are 
ordinarily  small.  There  is  some  evidence,  however,  that  changes  in  inventories  of  steel  ingots,  semifinished 
steel/  and  standard  types  of  finished  steel  in  the  hands  of  producers  may  at  times  be  quite  large.  Such 
changes  of  inventories  in  the  hands  of  producers  are  relevant  to  the  discussion  of  this  paper  only  if  it  is  neces- 
sary to  derive  estimates ;3f  steel  sales  from  figures  on  steel  production.  For  a  discussion  of  the  latter  problem 
see  Appendix  VIII,  Section  1. 


13918       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

F.    STEEL  IS  NOT  SOLD  IN  A  SINGLE  ONE-PBICB   MARKET  2' 

Largely  because  steel  producers  and  steel  buyers  are  located  over  a  wide  area, 
and  also  because  it  is  impossible  at  all  times  for  all  buyers  and  sellers  of  steel  to 
have  "perfect  knowledge  of  the  market,"  there  tend  to  exist  at  any  time  certain 
differentials  between  the  prices  paid  for  the  same  type  of  steel  by  different  buyers." 
These  differentials  are  of  two  main  types: 

(1)  First  there  are  the  more  or  less  permanent  price  differentials  between 
buyers  in  different  geographic  areas.  These  differentials  have  arisen  partly 
from  varying  costs  of  assembling  raw  materials  and  converting. them  into 
finished  products  at  different  locations,  partly  from  varying  costs  of  trans- 
portation of  the  finished  product  into  different  areas,  partly  from  the  forces 
of  competition,  and  partly  from  certain  long  established  institutional  arrange- 
ments in  the  pricing  of  steel. ^^  These  same  forces,  however,  tend  to  keep  the 
differentials  more  or  less  constant,  so  that  year  to  year  changes  in  the  price 
of  steel  are  about  the  same  in  all  areas.^* 

(2)  The  second  type  of  price  differential  is  the  concession  from  the  pre- 
vailing price.  Because  of  competition  among  steel  producer.'^,  it  is  obviously 
advantageous  at  certain  times  for  certain  steel  producers  to  offer  steel  at  lower 
prices  than  their  competitors."  By  so  doing  they  can  often  take  a  substantial 
share  of  the  steel  market  away  from  competing  steel  companies. ^^  However, 
the  same  forces  of  competition  require  that  such  price  concessions  be  kept 
from  the  knowledge  of  competitors;  otherwise  the  concessions  will  be  met  and 
become  general."  When  concessions  do  become  general,  data  on  the  price 
cuts  ordinarily  become  market  knowledge  available  to  the  steial, trade  journals 
who  report  "going"  market  prices. ^^ 

The  combination  of  these  two  types  of  price  differentials  means  that  at  any  time 
there  tends  to  be  more  than  one  price  for  the  same  type  of  steel.  Thus  there 
arises  the  problem  of  combining  these  prices  into  single  composite  prices  for  the 
various  types  of  steel. 2' 

IV.  Method  of  Analysis 

In  order  to  make  the  discussion  of  the  following  pages  clear  it  is  necessary  to 
define  the  terms  "quantity  of  steel  sold,"  "products-made-from-steel,"  "inven- 
tories of  steel  in  the  hands  of  producers  of  products-made-from-steel,"  and 
"jobbers'  stocks." 

(i)  By  quantity  of  steel  sold  is  meant  the  physical  quantity,  i.  e.,  tonnage  of 
steel  sold  by  steel  producers. 

(ii)  A  product-made-from-steel  is  any  finished  producers'  or  consumers' 
good  {not  service)  into  which  steel  enters  as  an  actual  raw  material  of  produc- 
tion. Automobiles,  steel  bridges,  rails-laid  are  examples.  Products-made- 
from-steel  are  of  two  broad  categories: 

(a)  Products-made-from-steel  produced  for  sale.  Automobiles,  house- 
hold appliances,  agricultural  implements  are  in  general  examples  of 
this  type. 

(b)  Products-made-from-steel  produced  for  the  producer's  own  use. 
Rails-laid,  bridges  and  highways,  pipe-lines-laid  are  examples  of  this 
category. 


»i  This  section  is  not  to  be  interpreted  either  as  an  attempt  to  describe  fully  or  to  appraise  the  pricing  and 
sellin?  arrangements  in  the  market  for  steel. 

"  Obviously  this  problem  is  not  confined  to  the  marketing  of  steel.  Such  price  differentials  will  almost 
always  arise  when  there  is  more  than  one  seller  and  one  buyer. 

"  Discussions  of  the  baslng-point  method  of  pricing  are  especially  relevant  here.  See  the  description  in 
Daugherty,  de  Chazeau  and  Stratton,  Economics  of  the  Iron  and  Steel  Industry  (McOraw-Hill  Book  Com- 
pany, New  York.  1937),  Vol.  I,  pp.  533-544. 

"  Mill  net  indexes  for  different  basing  point  areas  support  this  conclusion. 

"  Price  concessions  are  especially  advantageous  (from  the  short-run  point  of  view  of  the  individual  seller) 
for  producers  (I)  having  relatively  small  steel  producing  capacity  (2)  operating  at  a  low  percentage  of  capacity. 
By  making  concessions  such  producers  may  gain  enough  business  to  raise  their  operation  to  a  rate  at  which 
they  can  make  substantial  profit  gains  (or  loss  reductions). 

M  Sec  the  recent  discussion  in  Paul  M.  Sweczy,  "Demand  under  Conditions  of  Oligopoly,"  Journal  of 
Political  Economy,  v.  XLVII,  No.  4  (Aug.,  1939),  pp.  568  et  seq. 

>'  See  Sweezy,  op.  cit. 

"  Undoubtedly  there  are  times  when  price  concessions  arc  important,  and  when  it  is  difficult  for  the  trade 
Journals  to  verify  or  measure  the  extent  of  the  concessions.  Ordinarily  the  trade  journals  can  measure  the 
extent  of -the  concessions  only  when  the  market  for  some  type  of  steel  "breaks  wide  open." 

'•  This,  too,  is  a  difllcult  index  number  problem  that  has  never  been  satisfactorily  solved.  Ideally  the 
solution  requires  separate  demand  analyses  for  each  group  of  buyers  subject  to  the  same  price  differentials. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        139]  9 

(iii)    By  inventories  of  steel  in  the  hands  of  producers  of  -products-ynade-from- 
steel — or  simply  steel  inventories — is  meant  the  total  of: 

(a)  The  physical  quantity  of  steel  on  order  and  held  in  raw  material 
inventories  by  producers  of  products-made-from-steel;  and 

(b)  The  equivalent  measure  of  the  amount  of  steel  held  by  producers 
in  work-in-process  inventories  (partiallv  fabricated  products-made- 
from-steel). ^o 

(iv)   The  term  jobbers'  stocks  means  the  physical  amount  of  steel  held  by 
jobbers — i.  e.,  steel  middlemen. 

The  quantity  o-f  steel  sold  in  any  year  then  is  obviously  equal  to  the  number  of 
units  of  products-made-from-steel  produced  in  that  year  multiplied  by  the  average 
amount  of  steel  used  in  the  production  of  each,  plus  the  net  change  in  steel  inven- 
tories from  the  beginning  to  the  end  of  that  year  plus  the  similar  net  change  in 
jobbers'  stocks. 

For  example,  suppose  there  is  only  one  type  of  product-made-from  steel,  say 
automobiles.  During  the  year  automobile  producers  manufacture  5  million  cars 
using  1.5  gross  tons  of  steel  in  the  production  of  each  car.  Then  7.5  million  gross 
tons  of  steel  would  be  required  to  produce  the  5  million  cars.  At  the  beginning 
of  the  year  automobile  producers  held  0.5  million  gross  tons  of  steel  in  steel  inven- 
tories (in  unfabricated  form  or  in  equivalent  measure  in  work-in-process),  and  1.0 
million  gross  tons  at  the  end  of  the  year.  It  is  obvious  then  that  automobile  pro- 
ducers (producers  of  products-made-from-steel)  must  have  bought  8.0  million  gross 
tons  of  steel  during  the  year,  7.5  million  of  which  was  used  in  prodiiction  and  0.5 
miUion  to  increase  their  .steel  inventories.  Of  this  8.0  million  tons,  7.0  million 
were  bought  directly  from  steel  producers,  and  1.0  million  from  jobbers.  Jobbers 
meanwhile  increased  their  stocks  from  1.0  million  to  2.0  million  tons,  so  that  they 
must  have  bought  2.0  million  tons  from  steel  producers,  1.0  million  to  increase 
their  stocks,  and  1.0  to  sell  to  producers  of  products-made-from-steel. 

Steel  producers  then  must  have  sold  9  milhon  gross  tons  of  steel  during  the  year: 

7.5  million  of  which  went  into  the  production  of  products-made-from-steel; 
0.5  million  to  increase  the  steel  inventories  of  producers  of  products-made- 
from-steel;  and 
1.0  million  to  increase  jobbers  stocks. 

It  is  therefore  clear  that  in  determining  the  effect  of  a  change  in  the  price  of 
steel  on  the  quantity  of  steel  sold. in  any  year,  it  is  necessary  to  find  out  how  such 
a  price  change  would  affect: 

(i)   The  physical  volume  of  production  of  products-made-from-steel. 
(ii)   The  average  quantity  of  steel  used  in  the' production  of  each  unit  of 
product-made-from-steel. 

(iii)   The  net  change  in  steel  inventories, 
(iv)  The  net  change  in  jobbers  stocks. 

It  will  be  helpful  to  consider  how  each  of  these  is  determined. 

(1)  Volume  of  Production  of  Products- Made-from-Steel.  The  output  (number 
of  units)  of  products-made-from-steel  in  any  year  may  be  looked  upon  as  made 
of  three  parts: 

(a)  The  quantity  of  such  products  sold. 

(b)  The  net  change  in  producers'  inventories  of  products-made-from-steel 
produced  for  sale. 

(c)  The  output  of  products-made-from-steel  manufactured  for  the  pro- 
ducer's own  use. 

The  sum  of  the  first  two  is  obviously  equal  to  the  output  ci  products-made- 
from-steel  produced  for  sale. 

(a)  The  main  factors  which  determine  the  volume  of  sales  of  products- 
made-from-steel  have  been  discussed  in  Sections  III-B  and  III-D.  Since 
the  price  of  steel  will  in  general  affect  the  volume  of  sales  only  indirectly 
through  Its  effects  on  the  prices  of  products-made-from-steel.  the  problern 
becomes  the  two-fold  one  of  first  isolating  the  influence  of  the  prices  of  prod- 
ucts-made-from-steel on  their  sales,  and  then  determining  how  the  price  of 
steel  affects  prices  of  products-made-from-steel. 

This  second  problem  is  itself  an  extremely  diflScult  one,  for  the  prices  of 
products-made-from-steel  depend  on  many  factors  beside  the  price  of  steel 


>"  That  is,  the  amount  of  steel  used  In  the  production  of  inventories  of  partially  finished  products- 
from-steel. 


13920  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  price  of  steel  will  exert  its  eflfect  on  the  price  of  products-made-from-steel 
through  its  effect  on  their  costs  of  production,  and  the  importance  of  the 
effect  will  depend  in  large  measure  on  the  importance  of  steel  costs  in  the 
total  unit  costs  of  productioni 

In  general  it  seems  likely  that  an  increase  in  the  price  of  steel,  other  things 
remaining  the  same,  will  increase  unit  costs  of  production  and  thereby  the 
prices  of  products-made-from-steel.  The  increase  in  the  prices  of  products- 
made-from-steel  would  probably  lead  to  a  reduced  number  of  units  sold. 
For  a  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel,  the  converse  is  probably  true. 
Moreover,  it  is  reasonable  to  assume  that  ordinarily: 

(i)  Sales  of  products-made-from-steel  will  not  be  very  responsive  to 
changes  in  their  prices.     That  is,  changes  in  the  prices  of  products- 
made  from-steel  do  not  lead  to  much  larger  percentage  changes  in  sales.'' 
(ii)   Changes  in  the  unit  costs  of  production  of  products-made-from- 
steel  lead  to  approximately  equivalent  changes  in  their  prices. 

(iii)  Changes  in  the  price  of  steel  generally  lead  to  changes  in  the  costs 
of  production  of  prodncts-made-from-steel  in  approximately  the  pro- 
portion of  unit  steel  costs  to  total  unit  costs  of  production. 
Since  steel  costs  are  generally  only  a  small  fraction  of  the  total  costs  of  pro- 
duction of  products-made-from-steel,  it  follows  that  one  may  reasonably 
expect  changes  in  the  price  of  steel  to  lead  to  much  smaller  percentage  changes 
(in  the  opposite  direction)  in  the  sales  of  products-made-from-steel. 

(b)  The  size  of  inventories  (in  the  hands  of  producers)  of  products-made- 
from-steel  produced  for  sale  depends  in  major  part  on : 

(i)  The  current  and  expected  volume  of  sales  of  products-made-from- 
steel. 

(ii)  Current  and  expected  labor  costs  of  production  of  products-made- 
from-steel. 

(iii)  The  current  and  expected  length  of  time  required  to  make 
delivery  on  orders  of  products  made-from-steel. 
Of  these  three  factors  it  seems  reasonable  to  expect  that  only  the  first  would 
be  significantly  affected  by  changes  in  steel  prices.  Since  net  changes  of 
inventories  of  products-made-from-steel  tend  to  be  small  relative  to  sales  ana 
since  sales  are  only  slightly  responsive  to  changes  in  the  price  of  steel,  it  thus 
seems  likely  that  steel  price  changes  are  of  negligible  importance  in  affecting 
steel  sales  through  their  effects  on  inventories  of  products-made-from-steel. 

(c)  The  major  factors  determining  the  output  of  products-made-from- 
steel  produced  for  the  maker's  own  use  have  been  discussed  in  section  III'-D. 
The  price  of  steel  will  affect  the  output  of  such  products  mainly  through  its 
effects  on  tb-^ir  costs  of  production,  maintenance,  and  operation.  Since  the 
output  of  durable  producers'  goods  is  probably  not  very  responsive  to  changes 
in  their  costs  of  production,  operation,  and  maintenance,  and  since  steel  costs 
are  generally  only  a  very  small  part  of  such  costs,  changes  in  the  price  of  steel 
lead  to  much  smaller  percentage  changes  (in  the  opposite  direction)  in  the 
output  of  products-made-from-steel  manufactured  for  the  producers'  own 
use. 

(2)  The  Average  Amount  of  Steel  Used  in  the  Production  of  Each  Unit  of 
Products-Made-From-Steel.  In  section  III-B  it  was  pointed  out  that  the 
amount  of  steel  used  per  unit  of  output  of  a  product-made-from-steel  depends 
largely  on: 

(a)  The  technological  characteristics  of  the  product-made-from-steel;  of 
steel  and  substitute  raw  materials;  and  of  the  production  methods. 

(b)  The  price  of  steel. 

(c)  The  cost  of  using  substitutes  for  steel. 

"The  first  set  of  factors  (a)  however,  tend  to  change  very  slowly,  so  that 
they  may  be  classed  as  "long-run"  factors  which  are  relatively  unimportant 
in  determining  year  to  year  fluctuations  in  the  average  amount  of  steel  used 
per  unit  of  product-made-from-steel. 

A  rise  (or  fall)  in  the  price  of  steel  relative  to  the  cost  of  using  substitutes 
will  ordinarily  lead  to  a  decrease  (or  increase)  in  the  amount  of  steel  used  per 
unit  of  product-made-from-steel.  However,  it  is  extremely  doubtful  if  a 
change  in  steel  prices  in  any  year  has  more  than  a  negligible  effect  in  induc- 
ing substitution  in  that  year  (or  even  in  the  next  two  or  three).  The  reasons 
for  this  are  obvious: 

(i)  The  tastes  of  buyers  of  products-made-from-steel  tend  to  change 
very  slowly,  and  thus  retard  the  rate  of  substitution. 

"  The  demand  for  durable  goods  is  generally  not.  very  elastic. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13921 

(ii)  There  are  a  limited  number  of  ^dbstitutes  that  are  economically 
and  technically  suitable.  Moreover  technical  conditions  of  production 
rigorouslj^  limit  the  amount  of  substitution  that  can  take  place. 

(iii)  The  use  of  substitutes  for  steel,  or  the  substitution  of  steel  for 
other  factors  of  production  generally  requires  great  changes  in  the  type 
of  plant,  equipment,  and  labor  required.  A  change  in  the  price  of  steel 
relative  to  the  cost  of  substitutes  must  normally  be  substantial  and 
persist  for  several  years  before  the  investment  and  labor  training  costs 
required  by  substitution  will  be  undertaken. 
(3)  Net  Changes  in  Inventories  of  Steel  in  the  Hands  of  Producers  of  Products- 
Made-From-Steel,  and  Net  Changes  in  Jobbers'  Stocks. 

The  main  factors  determining  net  changes  in  inventories  of  steel  in  the  hands  of 
producers  of  products-made-from  steel  and  net  changes  in  jobbers'  stocks  were 
discussed  in  section  III-E,  and  will  not  be  elaborated  further  here. 

Once  it  is  known  how  (1)  the  output  of  products-made-from-steel,  (2)  the 
average  quantitj'  of  steel  per  unit  of  this  output,  (3)  inventories  of  steel,  and  (4) 
jobbers'  stocks  are  determined— including  the  influence  of  the  price  of  steel  in 
such  determination,  then  it  will  be  evident  how  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  is  deter- 
mined, ^nd  how  steel  price  changes  would  affect  the  quantity  of  steel  sold. 

Although  the  above  approach  is  ideal  in  that  it  enables  the  analyst  to  get  a  clear 
picture  of  the  separate  ways  the  price  of  steel  acts  in  determining  the  quantity  of 
steel  sold,  it  is  impossible  to  follow  it  here.  Information  is  lacking  at  critical 
points: 

(1)  Data  on  the  output  of  important  products-made-from-steel  are  lacking. 
Moreover,  even  if  output  data  were  complete,  the  great  diversity  of  products- 
made-from-steel  as  well  as  the  fact  that  they  change  in  nature  from  year  to 
year  makes  the  problem  of  combining  them  into  an  economic  composite  an 
almost  impossible  one.^^ 

(2)  Data  on  the  quantity  of  steel  used  in  the  production  of  different  types 
of  products-made-from-steel,  as  well  as  data  on  steel  inventories  and  jobbers' 
stocks  are  also  almost  completely  unavailable. 

Thus  it  might  seem  that  the  whole  problem  would  have  to  be  stranded  without 
■dv,  answer.  However,  it  is  obvious  from  the  discussion  of  the  previous  pages 
that  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  depends  upon  the  factors  which  determine  (R)  the 
output  of  products-made-from-steel,  (S)  the  average  quantity  'of  steel  per  unit 
of  the  output,  (T)  steel  inventories,  and  (L'^)  jobbers'  stocks.  Thus  if  the  most 
important  of  these  basic  determining  factors  can  be  measured,  if  such  measures 
are  available,  and  if  reasonable  hypotheses — determined  from  economic  logic  and 
empirical  observation — can  be  set  up  as  to  the  relation  between  these  factors,  then 
the  problem  may  not  be  insoluble.  However,  it  should  be  obvious  that  the  results 
obtained  by  such  procedure  will  not  be  as  conclusive  as  those  obtained  by  the 
approach  outlined  on  preceding  pages,  since  there  will  not  be  the  intermediate 
checks  on  hypotheses  as  to  the  demand  relationships  that  the  first  approach  offers. 

The  problem  remaining  then  is  a  threefold  one: 

(1)  The  clear  definition  and  measurement  of  the  most  important  factors 
determining  the  above  economic  variables  (R),  (S),  (T),  and  (U). 

(2)  The  setting  up — on  a  priori  and  empirical  grounds — of  an  hypothesis 
as  to  the  way  these  factors  act  together  in  determining  (R),  (S),  (T),  and  (U), 
and  thus  the  quantity  of  steel  sold. 

(3)  The  statistical  testing  of  the  hypothesis. 

V.  Factors  Which  Might  Be  Expected  to  Influence  the  Quantity  of  Steel 

Sold  ^3 

From  the  discussion  of  the  previous  pages  it  is  clear  that  the  following  factors 
might  reasonably  be  expected  to  influence  the  quantity  of  steel  sold: 

(1)  The  price  of  steel — including  both  the  level  and  the  direction  of  change. 

(2)  Consumers'  disposable  cash  income. 

(3)  The  distribution  of  the  income  among  income  classes. 

(4)  The  stock  (number  of  units  and  efficiency)  of  durable  goods — both 
consumers'  and  producers'. 

(5)  The  cost  of  living. 

(6)  The  prices  of  goods  and  services  which  compete  with  products-made- 
from-steel  for  the  outlays  of  producers  and  consumers. 

(7)  The  costs  of  maintaining  and  operating  products-made-from-steel. 

-32  See  section  III-C. 

"  See  Appendix  VIII  below  for  further  liscussion  of  the  problem  of  defining  and  measuring  the  important 
factors  m  the  demiind  for  steel. 


13922       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(8)  Industrial  profits. 

(9)  The  psychological  atmosphere — i.  e.,  producers'  and  consumers'  anti- 
cipation as  to  future  economic  conditions. 

(10)  Industrial  production-. 

Since  some  of  these  variables  are  very  highly  related  to  others,  however,  and 
since  others  tend  to  change  slowly  and  smoothly  from  year  to  year,  certain  of 
them  were  omitted  in  the  actual  analysis.  The  factors  which  were  used  in  the 
final  statistical  analysis  were: 

(1)  The  price  of  steel — both  its  level  and  direction  of  change. 

(2)  Industrial  production — both  its  level  and  direction  of  change. 

(3)  Consumers'  income — both  its  level  and  direction  of  change. 

(4)  Industrial  profits— both  its  level  and  direction  of  change. 

(5)  The  cost  of  living. 

(6)  A  time-trend  variable. 

As  will  be  pointed  out  below  ^*  these  six  factors  can  be  taken  as  approximately 
representing  all  of  the  preceding  ten. 

Vri.  The  Period  Studi'=:d 

The  period  1919  to  1938  was  chosen  for  analysis  for  the  following  reasons: 

(1)  It  was  a  long  enough  period  to  provide  observations  on  the  nature  of 
the  demand  for  steel  under  practically  all  types  of  conditions  so  that  somewhat 
general  inferences  could  be  drawn  from  the  data.  The  period  covered  includes 
both  years  of  boom  and  years  of  dechne.^' 

(2)  This  period  is  of  more  current  interest  than  earlier  periods,  because 
the  inferences  drawn  are  of  more  accurate  current  application. 

(3)  Data  for  years  prior  to  1919  are  very  often  not  available.^' 
However,  after  the  analysis  was  begun  it  -^as  found  desirable  to  exclude  the 

years  1919-1921  from  some  of  the  demand  relations.  The  analysis  indicated 
that  the  situation  in  these  three  years  was  abnormal  because  of  the  World  War. 
The  magnitude  and  the  direction  of  the  fluctuations  in  economic  activity  were  not 
typical  of  the  rest  of  the  period,  and  tl;ie  inclusion  of  these  years,  it  was  thought, 
obscured  the  ordinary  steel  demand  relations.  The  statistical  analysis,  however, 
was  in  most  cases  carried  through  for  both  the  complete  and  the  abbreviated 
periods. 

Annual  data^  rather  than  monthly  data  or  data  for  periods  longer  than  a  year, 
were  selected  for  analysis  for  three  reasons: 

(1)  Monthly  data  were  not  available  for  some  of  the  series. 

(2)  The  use  of  monthly  data  unnecessarily  complicates  the  analysis  for 
the  purposes  of  this  paper  because  it  introduces  short-term  factors — such  as 
seasonal  variations  and  short-run  speculative  activity — which  are  practically 
excluded  by  using  annual  data." 

(3)  The  use  of  longer-period   data   was   considered   undesirable   because 

(a)  A  much  longer  period  of  years  would  have  to  be  studied  in  order 
to  get  a  sufficient  number  of  observations. 

(b)  The  effect  of  year  to  year  changes  in  demand  conditions  on  steel 
sales  was  desired. 

(e)  It  is  extremely  difficult  to  isolate  the  causative  effect  of  price  when 
longer-period  data  are  used.  The  use  of  longer-period  data  introduces 
many  new  factors  into  the  analysis  which  can  be  considered  as  unim- 
portant in  studying  year  to  year  changes. 

VII.  The  Demand  Relation  Hypotheses  '* 

The  final  problem  remaining  prior  to  the  actual  statistical  determination  of 
the  demand  for  steel  is  that  of  setting  up  an  economically  logical  hypothesis  as 
to  the  way  the  factors  considered  in  section  V  act  together  in  determining  the 
quantity  of  steel  sold.    This  is  by  far  the  most  important  part  of  the  whole  analysis 

X  See-section  VII-A. 

«  When  annual  data  8i«  used,  the  statistical  technique  here  employed  requires  a  period  as  long  ss  fifteen 
of  twenty  years  in  order  to  get  a  suS'cient  number  of  observations.  The  reasons  for  this  are  tecbrlcsl  and 
will  not  be  discussed  here. 

3«  For  example,  rebaMe  ^lata  on  consumers'  Income,  industrial  profits,  the  ccst  of  living,  and  industrial 
production  are  lot  avsilabVin  good  form  before  1919. 

"  Ideally,  of  course,  it  wo  id  be  desirable  to  use  monthly,  or  even  shoiter  p^iod  data,  since  intra-year 
variaiions  tend  to  alTect  anrtual  measures.  However,  th«  extra  analysis  was  considered  to  be  too  great  to 
compensate  (or  the  small  loss  of  Information  Involved  in  using  annual  data. 

»  See  Roos  and  7c  n  Szeliskl,  op.  cit.,  section  III. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  TOWER  13923 

of  the  demand  for  steel.  It  is  obvious  that  the  final  inferences  drawn — concerning 
the  influence  of  the  price  of  steel  on  the  quantity  of  steel  sold — will  depend  on  the 
demand  relation  hypothesis  set  up. 

The  problem  of  setting  up  a  demand  relation  hypothesis  for  steel  is  a  perplexing 
one.  Products-made-from-steel  are  so  numerous  ana  so  diverse  that  it  is  almost 
impossible  to  analyze  the  way  economic  factors  act  together  in  determining  the 
output  of  even  the  most  important.  Moreover,  data  which  would  be  helpful  are 
lacking  at  critical  points.  Then,  too,  information  as  to  the  economic-technical 
problem  of  the  amount  of  steel  used  per  unit  of  p»'oducts-made-f  rom  steel  is  almost 

Chart  1 


DEMAND  FOR  STEEL  AND  INFLUENCING  FACTORS 

IN  UNITED  STATES 


S2« 

si 


11-: 


STEEL  INGOT 

/\ 

J 

/ 

s 

1^1^ 

\ 

1 

, 

\ 

/ 

1 

/ 

BOOKINGS^ 

\ 

\ 

f 

I. 

\ 

I 

> 

N 

WteeH 

\ 

^ 

V 

^ 

^, 

f 

\ 

1 

1 

^ 

^ 

<^ 

> 

1 

^^ 

-• 

k^ 

,Jci..lcoL 

,' 

/ 

zi 

">, 

J 

\ 

*^^ 

\ 

INCOME  1  , 

'"' 

"•s 

•< 

^ 

r-' 

^ 

V 

\ 

N 

f' 

»- 

/ 

PROFITS 

\ 

/ 

> 

/ 

\ 

/ 

\ 

/ 

/ 

N 

f 

/ 

-L-i41- 

^, 

/ 

V 

.^ 

/- 

PRODUCTION 

(I921. 25-1001 

-•, 

/ 

\ 

<^ 

1 

> 

V 

Fl^ 

^ 

W 

_ 

- 

y 

U 

H 

ISHED 

ST 

;el 

completely  unavailable.     A  similar  situation  exists  for  the  problem  of  setting  up 
an  hypothesis  as  to  the  determination  of  steel  inventories. 

The  lack  of  information  at  critical  points,  and  the  absence  of  a  completely 
suitable  body  of  economic  theory  have  forced  recourse  to  what  is  largely  an 
empirical  determination  of  the  demand  hypothesis. 


A.    ACTUAL    VARIABLES    INCLUDED    IN    THE    DEMAND    RELATIOI^    HYPOTHESIS 

Five  general  hypotheses  as  to  the  actual  variables  to  be  incl-uded  in  the  demand 
relation  hj'pothesis  were  set  up.  The  basic  variables  included  in  these  various 
hypotheses  are  shown  in  Chart  1  and  Appendix  I. 


13924  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  five  general  hypotheses  were: 

The  quantity  of  steel  sold  '»  depends  upon: 

(h-1)  The  price  of  steel,*"  and  the  volume  of  industrial  production." 
(h-2)  A  time-trend  variable  in  addition  to  those  of  (h-1). ^ 
(h-3)  The  same  variables  as  (h-2)  and  in  addition  two  variables 
measuring  respectively  the  rate  of  change  in  the  price  of  steel 
and  the  rate  of  change  in  the  volume  of  industrial  production. <* 
(h-4)   The  price  of  steel/"  a  time-trend,  consumers'  supernumerary 

income,"  and  industrial  profits." 
(h-5)   The  same  variables  as  (h-4),  and  in  addition  three  variables 
measuring  respectively  the  rates  of  change  in  the  price  of 
steel,  supernumerary  income,  and  industrial  profits.** 
In  (h-1)  it  was  assumed  that  industrial  production  measured  accurately  the 
composite  influence  of  all  factors  affecting  the  demand  for  steel  except  the  price  of 
steel.     It  was  assumed  that  industrial  production  reflected  the  composite  effect 
of  the  most  important  demand  factors,  viz.,  industrial  profits,  consumers'  income, 
the  replacement  pressure  on  the  stock  of  durable  goods,  and,  also  indirectly 
the  psychological  outlook.    -  Since  all  of  these  factors  have  actually  been  more  or 
less  highly   correlated   with  industrial  production,   such  an  assumption  is  not 
unreasonable. 

In  (h-2)  an  additional  time-trend  factor  was, included.  The  time-trend  was 
included  explicitly  as  a  variable  to  act  as  a  proxy  measure  for  all  factors  influencing 
the  demand  for  steel  which  tend  to  change  slowly  and  smoothly  over  a  long  period 
of  time.  Thus  it  serves  as  a  composite  measure  for  such  factors  as  population, 
the  size  of  the  stock  of  durable  goods,  and  long  time  changes  in  various  price  and 
cost  levels  (including  the  level  of  the  prices  of  steel),  industrial  technology,  and 
people's  tastes.  The  inclusion  of  such  a  variable  makes  it  possible  partly  to 
isolate  the  effects  of  these  long-run  factors. 

It  is  commonly  recognized  that  a  very  important  factor  determining  the  current 
level  of  activity  in  durable  goods  production — and  thus  in  steel  sales — is  the  busi- 
ness outlook  of  producers  and  consumers,  their  anticipations  as  to  future  prices, 
-  profits,  income,  etc.  Such  anticipations  are  very  largely  determined  by  the  ra- 
pidity and  direction  of  change  in  recent  and  current  business  activity.  If  present 
levels  of  activity  are  higher  than  they  have  been  in  the  recent  past,  it  is  easier  to 
believe  that  conditions  will  continue  to  improve  than  if  activity  is  currently  on 
the  decline.  For  this  reason  the  rate  of  change  of  industrial  production  was 
included  in  (h-3)  as  a  factor  measuring  changes  in  anticipations.  Similarly  the 
rate  of  change  in  the  price  of  steel  has  been  included  in  (h-3)  as  a  measure  of  steel 
buyers'  anticipations  as  to  the  near  future  price  of  steel. 

In  (h-4)  and  (h-5)  industrial  profits  and  consumers'  supernumerary  income  and 
their  respective  rates  of  change  have  been  substituted  for  industrial  production 
and  its  rate  of  change  to  measure  the  composite  of  factors  other  than  the  price  of 
steel  influencing  the  demand  for  steel. 

Of  the  five  general  hypotheses  it  would  seem  that  |(h-5)  is  probably  the  most 
complete  and  the  most  reasonable.  The  final  answer,  of  course,  cannot  be  given 
until  the  form  of  the  five  general  hypotheses  is  set  up  and  tested. 

'•  Measured  by  steel  ingot  production,  and  estimated  shipments  and  bookings.  See  Appendices  II 
and  Viri. 

*o  The  Iron  Age  '■omposite  price  of  finished  steel.    See  Appendix  VIII. 

*>  The  Federal  Reserve  Board  index  of  manufacturing  production  excluding  iron  and  steel.  See 
Appendices  VI  and  VIII. 

«  The  rates  of  change  are  for  any  year  in  each  case  measured  by  the  link  relative  for  that  year.  (The  link 
relative  is  equal  to  that  year's  figure  divided  by  the  figure  for  the  previous  year.) 

"  See  Appendix  IV. 

"  See  Appendix  V. 

«  The  measure  of  the  rates  of  change  is  the  link  relative,  except  for  profits  where  the  rate  of  change  is 
measured  by  first  differences.  (The  first  difference  for  any  year  is  equal  to  the  figure  for  that  year  less  the 
figure  for  the  previous  year.) 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13925 

B.  THE  FORM  OF  THE  DEMAND  RELATION  HYPOTHESIS 

The  next  step  in  the  analysis  is  the  formulation  of  an  hypothesis  as  to  the  way 
the  economic  variables  act  together  in  determining  the  demand  for  steel. 

Each  of  the  five  general  hypotheses  outlined  above  was  studied  by  familiar 
graphical  multi-factor  correlation  techniques,"  in  order  to  find  out 

(i)  What  mathematical  relation  seems  to  be  the  most  reasonable  expression 
of  the  relation  between  the  factors. 

(ii)  Whether  any  of  the  five  general  hypotheses  should  be  discarded  or 
modified. 

The  graphical  analysis  indicated  that  for  all  of  the  hypotheses  a  simple  additive 
relation  would  probably  give  as  satisfactory  results  as  any  other  (such  as  the 
multiplicative  or  combinations  of  the  additive  and  multiplicative). ■•' 

It  was  also  decided  from  the  graphical  analysis  to  use  only  (h-2),  (h-4),  and  a 
modification  of  (h-3)  which  excluded  the  rate  of  change  in  the  price  of  steel  ** 
and  the  time-trend. 

Thus  four  mathematical  relations  were  formulated  for  further  examination  by 
mathematical  statistical  techniques.     Translated  verbally  these  relations  were:" 

Relation  I. — Production  of  steel  ingots  and  castings  is  equal  to: 

Price  of  steel  multiplied  by  a  constant  value 
plus     Industrial  production  multiplied  by  (another)  constant  value 
plus     Time  (in  years)  multiplied  by  (another)  constant  value 
plus     a  constant  balancing  value. 

Relation  II. — The  same  as  relation  I  plus 

The  rate  of  change  of  industrial  production  multiplied  by  a  con- 
stant value  and  excluding  the  time-trend. 

Relation  III. — Estimated  steel  shipments  are  equal  to: 

Price  of  steel  multiplied  by  some  constant  value 
plus     Industrial  profits  multiplied  by  some  constant  valuef 
plus     Supernumerary  income  multiplied  by  some  constant  value 
plus     Time  (in  years)  multiplied  by  some  constant  value 
plus     a  constant  balancing  factor. 

Relation  IV. — The  same  as  relation  III  except  that  estimated  steel  bookings 
were  substituted  for  estimated  steel  shipments. ^o 

The  only  problem  remaining  was  to  find  the  numerical  values  of  the  various 
constant  multiplying  and  balancing  factors  in  the  relations.  Once  this  was  done 
it  was  easy  to  find  out  how  much  of  a  change  in  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  (as 
represented  by  bookings,  shipments,  or  ingot  production)  has  been  associated 
with  a  given  change  in  the  price  of  steel,  industrial  production  or  any  other  of 
the  independent  variables. 

«  See  Henry  Schultz,  op.  cit.,  pp.  184-186,  including  the  sources  cited  in  footnote  7  on  p.  185. 

*'  The  additive  relation  has  in  its  favor  the  simplicity  with  which  the  statistical  analysis  may  be  carried 
out.  More  complicated  forms  of  mathematical  relations  have,  of  course,  certain  logical  advantage.^  arising 
from  their  greater  generality.  It  is  well  known,  however,  that  if  it  is  desired  to  study  a  demand  relation  near 
the  average  values  of  its  variables,  the  linear  arithmetic  form  gives  practically  the  same  results  as  more  com- 
plex forms.  Since  it  was  considered  feasible  to  study  the  relation  only  near  its  average  values,  and  since  there 
was  no  clear  indication  from  the  graphical  analysis  that  a  more  complicated  form  was  a  more  likely  one,  the 
additive  relation  was  selected.  However,  the  statistical  analysis  was  also  carried  through  for  (h-2)  using  a 
simple  multiplicative  (linear  logarithmic)  relation.    See  Appendix  VII. 

<«  The  graphical  anaylsis  indicated  that  no  significant  information  would  be  added  by  the  rate  of  change 
terms  in  (h-5)  and  the  rate  of  change  of  the  price  of  steel  in  (h-3) ,  and  that  the  inclusion  of  these  terms  might 
break  down  the  statistical  analysis. 

<»  These  relations  are  stated  in  mathematical  form  in  Appendix  VII. 

"  See  Appendix  VII. 


13926 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
VIII.  The  Statistical  Findings 


The  constants  were  detennined  by  the  least  squares  multiple  correlation 
technique.*'     Final  equations  for  the  various  relations  are  shown  in  Appendix  VII. 

The  same  statistical  procedure  also  gives  the  percentage  of  the  total  variation 
in  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  over  the  period  studied  that  is  accounted  foi  by  the 
economic  factors  included  in  the  relations,  and  the  amount  that  can  be  directly 
attributed  to  the  separate  variations  of  each  of  the  factors.'^  These  percentages 
are  shown  below  in  Table  1.'^ 

Table  1 


Quantity  of  Steel  Sold  Measured 
by 

Percent  of  Variation  in  Quantity  of  Steel  Sold 

is 

Directly  attributable  to  variation  in 

Relation 
Number 

•s 

is 

|1 

a 

>> 

ii 

a  a 

ll 

1 

i 

I 

Production  of  Steel  Ingots  and 

96 

96 
91 
90 

0 
9 
9 

88 
81 

0 

II 

Production  of  Steel  Ingots  and 

'_ 

III 
IV 

Estimated  Steel  Shipments 

Estimated  Steel  Bookings 

41 
90 

19 

0 

Two  conclusions  are  indicated  by  Table  1: 

(1)  In  each  of  the  demand  relations,  the  included  factors  accounted  for 
90  percent  or  more  of  the  observed  variation  in  the  respective  measure  of 
steel  sales. 

(2)  Over  the  period  studied  only  a  small  fraction  (10  percent  or  less)  of 
the  variation  in  steel  sales  was  directly  attributable  to  variation  in  steel  prices, 
while  the  major  part  of  the  variation  was  accounted  for  by  included  factors 
other  than  the  price  of  steel. 

It  should  be  emphasized,  again,  however,  that  these  conclusions  depend  upon 
the  accuracy  of  three  assumptions: 

(a)  That  the  demand  relations  set  up  are  good  approximations  to  the  true 
demand  relations  both  as  to  factors  included  and  the  form  of  the  relation. 

(b)  That  the  variables  used  more  or  less  accurately  measure  what  they  are 
supposed  to. 

(c)  That  the  statistical  technique  yields  approximately  correct  constant 
values  for  the  demand  relation. 

In  appraising  the  second  conclusion  drawn  from  Table  1  it  should  be  kept  in 
mind  that  the  relative  proportion  of  the  total  variation  of  steel  sales  attributable 
to  variation  in  the  price  of  steel  over  any  period  will  depend  in  part  on  the  amount 
of  variation  in  steel  prices  relative  to  variation  in  the  other  factors.  Over  the 
period  1922  to  1938  relative  variation  in  steel  prices  was  considerably  less  than 
the  relative  variation  in  the  other  factors. 

SI  For  an  excellent  description  of  the  techniques  followed  see  Schultz,  op.  cit..  Appendix  C. 

"  For  a  rigorous  definition  of  the  term  "variation"  as  used  hern,  and  the  details  of  the  procedure  used  in 
attributing  variation  in  steel  sales  to  the  various  "causative"  economic  factors  see  Schultz,  op.  cit.,  pp. 
741-743.  Simply  stated,  the  percentage  of  variation  directly  attributable  to  any  factor  is  the  ratio  of  the 
variation  in  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  which  would  have  taken  place  if  only  that  factor  had  varied  in  the 
way  it  did,  to  the  variation  in  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  that  actually  took  place. 

M  Except  for  Relation  II  the  period  studied  was  1922  to  1938;  for  Relation  II,  it  was  1920  to  1938.  It  will 
be  noted  that  in  all  cases  the  sum  of  the  percentages  of  variation  directly  attributable  lo  the  separate  factors 
is  not  equal  to  the  total  variation  accounted  for  by  all  the  factors  in  the  relation.  The  reason  for  this  is  as 
follows:  In  obtaining  the  percentages  attributable  to  any  factor  we  assume  that  none  of  the  other  factors 
varied.  Actually,  of  course,  this  is  not  true;  all  of  the  factors  varied,  the  changes  in  some  factors  tending 
to  increase  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  while  other  changes  were  tending  to  decrease  sales.  The  net  result  of  all 
the  simultaneous  changes  is  the  amount  of  variation  accounted  for  by  all  the  factors. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  PDWER  13927 

A  more  useful  measure  of  the  importance  of  the  price  of  steel  is  the  elasticity  of 
demand  coefficient.  This  coefficient  is  the  ratio  of  the  percentage  change  in  the 
quantity  of  steel  sold  to  the  corresponding  percentage  change  in  the  price  of  steel, 
other  factors  being  fixed  at  some  level.** 

Table  2  below  shows  the  values  of  the.  elasticity  of  demand  found  in  the  four 
demand  relations  when  the  values  of  the  demand  factors  are  at  their  average 
levels  for  the  periods  studied." 

Table  2. — Elasticity  of  demand  for  steel 

Relation  number:  Elasikiiy 

I +0.  12 

II +0.52 

III -0.21 

IV -0.88 

The  values  are  consistent  in  this  very  important  respect:  they  indicate  that  at 
most  a  one  percent  decrease  in  the  price  of  steel  would  cause  {other  factors  remaining 
the  same)  less  than  a  one  percent  increase  in  steel  sales  {and  conversely) .  If  this  is 
true,  and  if  fluctuations  in  the  other  factors  continue  to  be  as  great  and  as  im- 
portant as  they  have  been  in  the  past,  the  volume  of  steel  consumption  cannot  be 
stabilized  by  compensatory  changes  in  the  price  of  steel. 

Which  of  the  above  values  of  the  elasticity  of  demand  is  the  most  likelj'?  The 
values  obtained  from  Relations  III  and  IV  are  probably  better  than  those  from 
I  and  II  for  the  following  reasons: 

(a)  On  a  priori  grounds  it  seems  reasonable  that  a  change  in  the  price  of 
steel  would  lead  to  a  chi  nge  in  the  opposite  direction  in  steel  sales. *^  Rela- 
tions I  and  II  both  indicate  positive  relations  between  steel  prices  and  sales. 

(b)  As  pointed  out  in  Appendix  VIII,  steel  ingot  production  is  probably 
not  as  accurate  a  measure  of  steel  sales  as  the  estimates  used  in  Relations  III 
and  IV. 

(c)  Industrial  production  (and  its  rate  of  change)  is  probably  not  as  good 
a  measure  of  the  composite  of  factors  other  than  price  of  steel  as  the  com- 
bination of  the  two  factors,  industrial  profits  and  supernumerary  income. 

The  diff'erenoe  in  the  values  obtained  from  Relations  III  and  IV  can  be  due  only 
to  the  diff"erence  between  the  estimates  of  steel  sales  used  in  each  case,  for  the 
relations  are  identical  in  other  respects.  From  Chart  1  it  is  apparent  that  fluctua- 
tions in  the  steel  bookings  figures  used  in  Relation  IV  tend  to  lead  industrial 
profits,  while  steel  shipments  (used  in  Relation  III)  do  so  to  much  less  degree. 
The  reasons  for  the  lag  of  shipments  behind  bookings  are  discussed  in  Appendix 
VIII.  In  Appendix  VIII  it  is  also  pointed  out  that  accounting  profit  figures  tend 
to  lag  behind  the  current  profit  situation  that  they  supposedly  measure.  An 
analysis  of  business  historj-  over  the  period  1919  to  1938  adds  additional  evidence 
that  the  profits  figures  ordinarily  reported  have  a  significant  lag. 

In  the  graphical  analyses  that  were  made  of  the  various  demand  relations,  there 
were  clear  indications  that  if  the  lags  of  shipments  and  industrial  profits  behind 
bookings  were  removed,  Relations  III  and  TV  w'ould  both  give  about  the  same 
results  for  the  elasticity  of  demand,  yielding  a  figure  of  0.3  to  0.4.  The  evidence 
and  argument  adduced  in  the  preceding  pages  of  this  paper  support  the  conclusion 
that  such  a  value^or  one  even  lower — for  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  is  not 
a  statistical  happenstance,  but  a  reality. 

Although  these  findings  are  not  absolutely  conclusive  in  establishing  this  very 
low  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel,  they  certainly  afford  no  basis  for  the  view  that 
the  price  of  steel  is  a  practical  medium  for  stabilizing  production. 

"  A  rigorous  mathemsitical  definition  of  the  elasticity  of  demand  is  given  in  Appendix  VII.  It  is  also 
shown  there  that  the  elasticity  of  demand  may  vary  as  the  price  of  steel  and  the  other  factors  influencing 
the  demand  for  steel  vary. 

55  These  values  of  the  elasticity  have  been  computed  at  the  arithmetic  mean  point  of  the  factors  influencing 
the  demand  for  steel. 

56  See  the  'iscussion  of  Section  IV. 


13928  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Appendix  I.  Basic  Series  Used  in  the  Statistical  Analysis 

The  basic  series  used  in  the  statistical  analysis  are  shown  below  in  Table  A-1. 
These  series  are  also  shown  in  Chart  1,  p.  21. 

Table  A-1. — Basic  Series  Used  in  Statistical  Analysis 


1910 
1920 
1921 
1922 
1923 
1924 
1925 
1926 
1927 
1928 
1929 
1930 
1931 
1932 
1933 
1934. 
1935. 
1936. 
1937. 
1938 


Steel 
Ingot 
Produc- 
tion > 
(thou- 
sands of 
gross 
tons) 


Steel 
Book- 
ings ' 
(thou- 
sands of 

gross 

and  net 

tons) 


Steel 

Ship- 
ments ' 

(thou- 
sands of 

gross 
and  net 

tons) 


20,783 
27,  217 
12,375 
23, 705 
29,173 
24,154 
29,639 
30,847 
28,827 
32,560 
36, 197 
26,280 
18, 431 
10,385 
15,607 
16,222 
21,050 
28,766 
31,620 
18, 176 


Indus- 
trial 

Produc- 
tion* 
(1923- 

25  =  100) 


Rate  of 
Change 
of  In- 
dustrial 
Produc- 
tion » 


Indus- 
trial 
Profits  • 
(bUlions 

of 
dollars) 


6.419 
4.468 
-0.055 
4.380 
5.867 
4.998 
6.971 
6.774 
5.880 
7.566 
8.083 
1.366 
-3. 145 
-5.375 
-2.379 
0.157 
1.674 
3.903 
3.872 
2.165 


Supernu- 
merary 

Income  ' 
(billions 

of 
dollars) 


35.5 
35.6 
37.5 
39.8 
40.6 
43.0 
46.8 
41.7 
34.1 

20!2 
25.1 
27:8 
36.0 


Com- 
posite 

Price  of 

Steel  • 

(cents 

per 

pound) 


3.115 
3.737 
2.437 
2.124 
2.697 
2.505 
2.334 
2.315 
2.202 
2.165 
2.209 
2.048 
1.957 
1.901 
1.879 
2.033 
2.058 
2.077 
2.464 
2.394 


Sources: 
■  Appendix  II,  T  ble  A-2,  column  (2). 
»  Appendix  II,  T  ible  A-2,  column  (5). 
'  Appendix  II,  1  able  A-2,  column  (7). 

*  Appendix  VI,  Table  A-6,  column  (6). 

•  These  are  the  link  relatives  of  the  figures  in  the  previous  column. 

«  Appendix  V,  Table  A-5,  column  (5).    The  figure  for  1937  which  was  actually  used  in  the  computations 
was  $3,959  billion.    For  this  and  the  1938  figure  see  Appendix  V,  p.  34. 
'  Appendix  IV,  Table  A-i,  column  (8). 
8  Iron  Age,  January  5,  1939,  pp.  198-199. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13929 

Appendix  II.  Estimation  of  Domestic  Bookings  and  Domestic  Shipments 
OF  Steel  for  Steel  Industry  as  a  Whole 

The  details  of  the  computations  used  in  estimating  domestic  bookings  and 
shipments  of  rolled  and  finished  steel  from  those  of  the  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 
are  shown  below  in  Table  A-2.     See  also  Appendix  VIII,  pp.  50-51. 

Table  A-2.^ — Estimation  of  bookings  and  shipments  of  steel  for  steel  industry  as  a 
whole,  1919-1988 


1919 
1920 
1921 
1922 
1923 
1924 
1925 
1926. 
1927. 
1928. 
1929. 
1930. 
1931. 
1932. 
1933. 
1934. 
1935. 
1936. 
1937. 


Production  of  Steel  Ingots  and  Steel 
for  Castings  (thousands  of  grcss  tons) 


United 
States  Steel 
Corpora- 
tion' 


Steel  in- 
dustry as  a 
whole ' 


Ratio  of 
(2)  to  (1)  3 


.0157 
.1855 
.8040 
.2138 
.2107 
.3019 
.4019 
.3782 
.4307 
.5637 
,5805 
.4332 
.5733 
.7755 


Domestic 
Bookings  of 

United 
States  Steel 

Corpora- 
tion <  (thou 
sands  of 
{rross  and 
net  tons) 


Estimated 
Domestic 
Bookings: 
Steel  In- 
dustry ' 
(thousands 
of  gross  and 
net  tons) 


25, 233 
30, 212 
7,609 
30,391 
25, 439 
26,  214 
30,557 
29,138 
28,488 
33,761 
39, 167 
26,  977 

17,  133 
9,129 

15,027 

18,  777 
22,751 

30',  212 
19,413 


Shipments 
of  Rolled 
and  Fin- 
ished Steel 
Products, 
Domestic, 
by  the 
United 
States  Steel 

Corpora- 
tion » (thou 
sands  of 
gross  tons 
and  net 
tons) 

(6) 


10,311 
12, 453 
6,832 
10,708 
13, 196 
10,  493 
12,  340 
12,971- 
11,860 
12,  701 
14:027 
10,801 
7,162 
3,742 
5,406 
5.392 
6,873 
10, 182 
11,588 
6,025 


Estimated 
Domestic 

Shipments: 
Steel  In- 
dustry ' 

(thousands 

of  gross  and 
net  tons) 


20,783 
27, 217 
12,325 
23,705 
29, 173 
24,154 
29,639 
30,847 
■2S,  827 
32,560 
36, 197 
26, 280 
18,431 
10, 385 
15,607 
16,  222 
21,050 
28,766 
31,620 
18, 176 


Sources: 
>  Records  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation. 

»  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute,  Annual  Statistical  Report  for  19S8,  p.  15. 
5  Column  (2)  divided  by  column  (1). 
'  Records  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation. 
»  Column  (4)  multiplied  by  column  (3). 
•  Records  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation.  , 
'  Columa  (6)  multiplied  by  column  (3). 


13930       CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Appendix  III.   Revision  of  the  U.  S.  Department  of  Commerce  Estimates 
OF  National  Income  Payments 

The  estimates  of  the  United  States  Department  of  Commerce  for  "national 
income  payments" — which  are  probably  the  best  estimates  of  "consumers'  cash 
income"  '  are  based  in  large  part  upon  another  of  their  national  income  estimates 
called  "national  income  paid  out".-  In  June,  1939,  the  estimates  for  the  latter 
were  revised  by  the  Department  of  Commerce,'  but  corresponding  revisions  were 
not  made  in  the  income  payment  series.  Thus  it  seemed  desirable  to  revise  the 
figures  for  income  payments  in  view  of  the  basic  revisions  in  the  "income  paid 
out"  series. 

'I'he  details  of  the  revision  are  shown  above  in  Table  A-3. 

The  revised  estimates  of  "national  income  paid  out"  are  shown  in  column  (1), 
and  the  unrevised  estimates  in  column  (2~i.  The  unrevised  estimates  of  "income 
payments"  are  shown  in  column  (3).  The  unremsed  estimates  of  "income  pay- 
ments" are  based  on  the  unrevised  estimates  of  "income  paid  out".''  The  difference 
between  the  two  (shown  in  column  4)  is  equal  to: 

"Direct  relief  payments," 

plus  "Benefit  payments  under  Social  Security  Act," 

plus  "Annuities  and  refunds  to  Federal  employees," 

plus  "Veterans  compensation"  (Soldiers'  Bonus), 

less  "Employer  contributions  under  the  Social  Security  Act,'" 

less  "Employee  contributions  under  the  Social  Security  Act," 

less  "Employee  contributions  under  the  Railroad  Retii'ement  Act," 

less  "Contributions  to  Federal  Retirement."  ' 

For  1938  the  sum  of  these  figures  was  equal  to  -$17  million. «  This  figure 
(-$17  million)  was  added  to  the  1938  revised  figure 'for  "income  paid  out" 
(column  1)  to  give  the  revised  1938  figure  for  income  payments  (column  5). 

For  the  years  1929  through  1937  the  differences  between  "revised  income  pay- 
ments" and  "revised  income  paid  out"  were  assumed  to  be  the  same  as  between 
the  corresponding  ..unrevised  figures.  These  differences  are  shown  in  column  (4); 
by  adding  these  figures  to  those  of  "revised  income  paid  out"  (column  1)  the 
reoised  estimates  of  income  payments  were  obtained  (column  5). 

'  Pee  Appendix  VIII,  pp.  49-50. 

s  Robert  R.  Nathan,  "Income  in  tlie  United  States,  1929-19,37."  a  bulletin  of  the  United  States  Depart- 
ment of  Commerce,  November,  1938. 

3  Robert  R.  Nathan,  "National  Income  in  1938  at  04  Billion  Dollars,"  Stirvey  of  Current  Business,  June, 
!939.  After  this  report  had  been  drafted,  revisions  in  the  income  payment  series  were  published  by  the 
United  States  Department  of  Commerce,  Survey  of  Current  Business,  October,  1939. 

'  See  tbe  sources  referred  to  in  footnotes  a  and  c  of  Table  A-3. 

s  See  Cone,  "Revised  Estimates  of  Monthly  Income  Payments  in  the  United  States,  1929-1938",  Sunev 
of  Current  Business,  October,  1938,  p.  15. 

«  This  figure  was  obtained  in  the  following  manner: 

In  the  source  referred  to  in  footnote  3  "employer  contributions  under  the  Social  Security  Act"  were  piven 
as  $1,119  million  for  1938.  "Employee  contributions  under  the  Social  Security  Act"  for  1938  were  assumed 
to  be  the  same  proportion  of  "Employer  contributions"  as  in  1937.  "Contributions  to  Federal  Retirement" 
were  assumed  to  bo  .$80  million;  they  had  been  $78  million  in  1936,  and  $80  million  in  1937  (See  Cone,  ibid.). 
Similarly  "Employee  contributions  to  Railroad  Retirement  Fund"  were  assumed  to  be  $fiO  million;  they 
had  been  $81  million  in  1937  (See  Cone,  ibid.).  "Annuities  and  refunds  to  Federal  employees"  was  assumed 
to  be  $60  million,  or  approximately  equal  to  the  1930  and  1937  figures  of  $58  million  and  $61  million  respectively 
(See  Cone,  ibid.). 

Bv  adding  monthly  figures  in  the  Surveij  of  Current  Busine.'is,  Mm.,  1939,  p.  19,  "Direct  relief  payments 
were  estimated  at  $1,06.'  million,  "Benefit  payments  under  Social  Security  Act"  at  $,503  million  and  "Vet- 
erans' compensation"  zero. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13931 


Table  A-3. — Revision  of  United  States  Department  of  Commerce  Figures  for 
National  Income  Payments  for  Their  June  1939  Revisions  of  National  Income 
Paid  Out,  1929-1938 

[Millions  of  dollars] 


National  Income  Paid  Out 

National 

Income 

Payments, 

Unrevised « 

(3) 

Unrevised 
National 
Income  Pay- 
ments Less 
Unreviiied 
National 
Income 
Paid  Out « 

(4) 

Year 

Revised  > 
(1) 

Unrevised » 
(2) 

Revised 

National 

Income 

Payments » 

(5) 

80,243 
74,414 
62,763 
49,296 
45,  565 
52,057 
55,814 
64,207 
70,694 
65,021 

78, 556 
73,290 
62,032 
49,024 
45,317 
51, 510 
55, 137 
62,586 
69,330 

78,574 
73,350 
63,117 
49,597 
45,921 
52,223 
56,086 
64.365 
68,971 
M,196 

18 

60 

1,085 

573 

604 

713 

949 

1,779 

-359 

-17 

1930 - 

63,848 

1932 

49, 869 

1933 — 

1934 

52, 770 

1935 

56,763 

1936 

65,986 

1937 

70,335 

1938 

65,004 

•  Robert  R.  Nathan,  "National  Income  In  1938  at  64  Billion  Dollars,"  Survey  of  Current  Business,  June, 
1939,  p.  12. 

'  Robert  R.  Nathan,  "Income  in  the  United  States,  1929-1937,"  a  bulletin  of  the  United  States  Depart- 
ment of  Commerce,  November,  1938,  p.  22. 

'  The  figures  for  1929  to  1935  are  the  sums  of  monthly  figtires  shown  in  the  source  referred  to  in  footnote  *. 
The  figures  for  1936  and  1937  are  from  Fref^erick  M.  Cone,  "Revised  Estimates  of  Monthly  Income  Payments 
in  the  United  States,  1929  to  1938,"  Sur.  iy  of  Current  Business,  October,  1938,  p.  15.  The  figure  for  1938  is 
the  sum  of  monthly  figures  in  the  Survey  gf  Current  Business,  March,  1939,  p.  19. 

*  Column  (3)  minus  column  (2). 
»  Column  (1)  plus  column  (4). 


12441)1-^-4  1—^)1.  20- 


13932  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Appendix  IV.  Computation  of  Supernumerary  Income 

Details  of  the  calculation  of  supernumerary  income  are  shown  below  in  Table 
A-4.     See  also  Appendix  VIII,  pp.  50-51. 

Table  A-4. — Calculation  of  Supernumerary  Income,  1919-1938 


Year 

Kuznets' 

come 

Pay- 
ments 10 

Indi- 
viduals I 
(billions 
of  current 
dollars) 

(1) 

United 
States 
Depart- 
ment of 
Com- 
merce 
Income 

Pay- 
ments ' 
(billions 
of  current 
dollars) 

(2) 

Consum- 
ers' In- 
come ' 
(billions 
of  current 
dollars) 

(3) 

National 
Indus- 
trial Con- 
ference 
Board, 
Index  of 
the  Cost 
of  Liv- 
ing* 
(Mar.. 
1935= 
100.) 

Mini- 
mum 
Cost  of 
Living 
Per  Per- 
son *  (cur- 
rent dol- 
lars) 

(5) 

Bureau 
of  the 
Census 
Mid-Year 
Poptila- 
tion  Es- 
timate 
for  the 
United 
States « 
(thou- 
sands of 
persons) 

(6) 

Total 
Income 
Required 
for  Mini- 
mum 
Cost  of 
Living  ' 
(billions 
of  dollars) 

(7) 

Super- 
numer- 
ary In- 
come • 
(billions 
of  dollars) 

(8) 

1919 

$57. 499 
67.056 
55. 177 
58.041 
65. 854 
66.  763 
69. 921 
72.823 
73. 381 
75.823 
79.808 

$57. 826 
67. 437 
55.  490 
58.  371 
66.  228 
67. 142 
70. 318 

73.  237 
73. 798 
70.  254 
80.261 

74.  474 
63.  848 
49.  869 
46.  169 
52.  770 
56. 763 
65.986 
70.  335 
65.004 

124.8 
144.1 
124.8 
118.8 
122.0 
123.5 
126.5 
127.2 
124.4 
122.7 
122.1 
117.9 
106.3 
95.0 
91.3 
96.8 
100.7 
103.4 
107.9 
105.4 

$281.8 
325.4 
281.8 

275^5 
278.9 
285.7 
287.2 
280.9 
277.1 
275.7 
266.2 
240.0 
214.5 
206.2 
218.6 
227.4 
233.5 
243.7 
238.0 

105, 003 
106,  543 
108, 208 
109, 873 
111,537 
113,202 
114,867 
116,532 
118, 197 
119,862 
121,.'i26 

123,  091 
124,113 

124,  974 

125,  770 

126,  626 

127,  521 
128,429 
129,257 
130. 215 

$29.59 
34.67 
30.49 
29.48 
30.73 
31.57 
32.82 
33.47 
33.20 
33.21 
33.50 
32.77 
29.79 
26.81 
25.93 
27.68 
29.00 
29.99 
31.50 
30.99 

$28  2 

1920 

ZJ  8 

1921 

25.0 

1922 

28  9 

1923  

35.5 

1924 

35  6 

1925 

37.5 

1926 

39.8 

1927 

40.6 

1928 

43.0 

1929 

$80,261 
74. 474 
63.848 
49. 869 
46. 169 
52.  770 
56.763 
65. 986 
70. 335 
65.004 

46.8 

1930 

41.7 

1931 

34.1 

1932 

23.1 

1933 

20.2 

1934 

25.1 

1935 

27.8 

1936 

36.  .1 

1937 

38.  o 

1938          »      .  — 

34.0 

'  Simon  Kuznets,  National  Income  and  Capital  Formation,  I919-I9S5,  National  Bureau  of  Economic 
research,  1937,  p.  24,  row  10. 

'  These  are  the  revisions  of  the  United  States  Department  of  Commerce  series  for  "monthly  income 
payments."    See  Appendix  III,  Table  A-3,  column  5. 

»  The  figures  for  1919  to  1928  are  column  (1)  times  1.00568;  the  figures  for  1929  to  1938  are  the  same  as  those 
of  column  (2).  The  figures  for  1919  to  1928  are -the  result  of  linking  the  fipurer,  in  column  (I)  to  those  of 
column  (2)  at  1929.  That  is,  the  figures  in  column  (1)  have  been  multiplied  by  the  ratio  of  the  1929  figure  of 
column  (2)  to  the  1929  figure  of  column  (1).    In  so  doing  it  was  assumed  that: 

(1)  The  1929  figure  of  column  (2)  was  the  correct  figure  for  consumers'  cash  income. 

(2)  That  Kuznets'  figures  for  1919  to  1928  were  "in  error"  in  the  ratio  of  his  1929  figure  to  that  of  column  (2). 
•  For  the  years  1919  to  1937  see  Survey  of  Current  Business,  19SS  Supplement,  p.  11.    The  1938  figure  in  the 

average  of  monthly  figures  for  1938  reported  in  Survey  of  Current  Business,  Mar.,  1939,  p.  20.  The  base  of 
these  figures  has  been  shifted  from  1923  =  100  to  Mar.,  1935=100. 

»  Obtained  by  multiplying  column  (4)  by  $2.2582  (or  by  dividing  column  (4)  by  100  and  multiplying  by 
$225.82)>  Essentially  what  has  been  done  is  to  assume  that  the  necessity  or  minimum  cost  of  living  per 
person  in  March,  1935,  was  $225.82  (Appendix  VIII,  p.  61)  and  that  it  varied  as  did  the  National  Industrial 
Conference  Board  index  of  the  cost  of  living. 

«  United  States  Department  of  Commerce,  Bureau  of  the  Census.  Statistical  Abstract  of  Vie  United  States, 
19S8,  p.  10. 

'  Column  (5)  multiplied  by  column  (6). 

'  Column  (7)  subtracted  from  column  (3).  The  resulting  figure  is  the -estimate  of  supernumerary  income, 
or  the  amount  of  cash  income  available  for  disposal  in  the  luxury  goods  market. 

Appendix  V.  Estimation  of  Indiustrial  Profits 

For  the  years  1919  to  1937  the  basic  sources  of  data  used  in  computing  indus- 
trial profits  were  the  Statistics  of  Income  reports  of  the  United  ^tates  Bureau  of 
Internal  Revenue.  The  formula  used  in  computing  industrial  profits  is  given  in 
Appendix  VIII.     Table  A-5  shows  the  details  of  the  computations. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13933 

Table  A-5. — Industrial  Profits  Estimated  From  the  Statistics  of  Income,  1919-19S7* 
[Thousands  of  dollars] 


Year 

Statutory 
Net  Income ' 

(1) 

Total 
Federal  Tax  > 

(2) 

Tax  Exempt 
Interest ' 

(3) 

Dividends 
Received 

From 

Domestic 

CorpOTations* 

(4) 

Industrial 
Profits" 

(5) 

1919 

$8,415,872 

5,873,531 

457, 829 

4,770,035 

6,307,974 

6,362,726 

7,621,056 

7,504,693 

6, 610, 146 

8,226,617 

8,739,758 

1,551,218 

-3,287,646 

-5, 643, 574 

-2,647,367 

94,1710 

1,696,949 

7,  326, 217 

7.354,003 

$2, 175, 342 

1, 625, 235 

701, 576 

783, 776 

937, 106 

881,550 

1, 170, 331 

1,229,797 

1, 130, 674 

1, 184, 142 

1,193,436 

71i;704 

398,994 

285,576 

423,068 

696,048 

736,125 

1, 191, 378 

1,  276, 184 

$178,648 
219,977 
188, 789 
394.042 
496, 202 
617,209 
619,846 
499:592 
600,826 
623,458 
636,697 
526,261 
541,713 
6H260 
691,586 
658,701 
713,646 
444,669 
476,302 

$8, 419, 078 

1920 

4,467,973 

1921 

—54,968 

1922 

4,380,301 

1923 

6, 867, 070 

1924 

4, 998, 385 

1925 

6, 970, 571 

1926 

6, 774, 488 

1927 

6,880,297 

7  665  933 

8,083,019 

1930 

1, 365, 776 

-3,144,826 

1932..       

-5,374,900 

1933 

-2,378,849 

1934 .. 

156,828 

1935.. - 

1, 674, 370 

1936 

$2, 676, 598 
2,682,227 

3,902,910 

1937 

3,871,894 

1  statistics  of  Income  for  19S6,  Pt.  II,  p.  47,  from  colomn  headed  "Net  income  less  deficit." 
'  Ibid.,  column  headed  "Total  Tax". 

'  Obtained  from  Mr.  Edward  White,  Chief  of  the  Statistical  Section  of  the  United  States  Bureau  of 
Internal  Revenue,  in  a  letter  of  July  14,  1939. 
<  Statisiict  of  Income  for  19S6,  Pt.  II,  p.  24,  from  column  headed  "Aggregate". 

•  The  sum  of  column  (1)  plus  column  (3)  minus  the  sum  of  column  (2)  plus  column  (4). 

♦  1937  figures  were  taken  from  a  preliminary  release  (Pres^ervlce,  No.  18-66)  of  the  TTnited  States  Treas- 
ury Department,  August  23, 1939. 

At  the  time  the  statistical  computations  for  this  paper  were  made,  the  aboVe 
figures  for  1937  were  not  available,  so  that  the  1937  figure  for  profits,  as  well  as 
that  for  1938  had  to  be  estimated  from  other  less  accurate  sources.  The  profits 
figures  reported  periodically  by  the  National  City  Bank  of  New  York  in  its 
monthly  economic  buUetin  were  used  for  this  purpose.'  These  profit  figures 
cover  reports  of  about  2,000  corporations,  and  show  profits  after  depreciation, 
interest,  taxes,  and  other  charges,  but  before  dividends. 

The  general  procedure  used  is  as  follows: 

A.  Estimating  Profits  for  1937: 

(1)  In  its  April  1,  1938,  bulletin  the  National  City  Bank  reported  profit 

figures  for  1936  and  1937  for  2,300  corporations  grouped  by  types 
of  business.  These  groups  were  then  re-grouped  into  business 
classes  comparable  to  those  used  in  the  Statistics  of  Income  for  1936. 

(2)  The  ratio  of  the  profit  figure  for  1936  for  any  group  computed  from 

the  Statistics  of  Income  to  that  reported  by  the  National  City  Bank 
was  then  computed. 

(3)  The  1937  profit  figure  for  that  group  as  reported  by  the  National 

City  Bank  was  then  multiplied  by  this  ratio,  giving  est^imated 
profits  for  1937  for  this  group. 

(4)  The  sum  of  all  such  estimated  group  profits  was  the  estimated  figure 

for  industrial  profits  for  1937. 

It  is  interesting  to  note  that  the  resulting  estimate  of$3.96  billion  is  only  about 
2  percent  larger,  than  the  profit  figure  reported  by  the  United  States  Bureau  of 
Internal  Revenue  for  1937.     (See  Table  A-5.) 

B.  Estimating  Profits  for  1938: 

(1)  In  its  April  1,  1939,  bulletin  the  National  City  Bank  reported  profits 
for  1937  and  1938  for  a  group  of  over  2,400  corporations.  These 
corporations  were  grouped  into  classes  corresponding  to  those 
used  in  estii^ating  profits  for  1937. 

'  See  the  economic  bulletins  of  the  National  City  Bank- of  New  York  for  April  1, 1938.  and  April  1,  1939 


139S4        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(2)  Since  the  report  for  April  1,  1939,  did  not  cover  exactly  the  same  cor- 
porations as  that  for  April  1,  1938,  the  group  totals  for  1937  of  the  1939 
report  differed  from  those  of  the  1938  report.  Thus  for  each  group 
the  ratio  of  the  1937  profit  figure  shown  in  the  1938  report  to  that  in 
the  1939  report  was  computed.  The  1938  figure  for  this  group  was 
then  multiplied  by  this  ratio. 

(3)  The  resulting  group  figure  was  then  multiplied  by  the  ratio  computed 
in  step  (2)  of  (A),  giving  estimated  1938  profits  for  that  group. 

(4)  The  sum  of  these  group  profit  figures  was  the  estimate  of  industrial 
profits  for  1938. 

The  estimated  profits  figures  for  1937  and  1938  were  (in  billions) : 

1937. -_ $3,959 

1938 $2.  165 

These  were  the  figures  actually  used  in  the  computations. 

Appendix  "VI.  Computation  of  Industrial  Production  Index 

It  was  decided  that  the  index  of  industrial  output  most  suitable  for  the  purposes 
of  this  paper  was  the  Federal  Reserve  Board's  Index  of  Manufacturing  Production 
with  the  iron  and  steel  production  subgroup  removed.' 

The  Federal  Reserve  Board  index  is  an  aggregative  type  index  with  fixed  weights. 
The  base  of  the  index  is  1923-25=100. 

The  procedure  for  removing  the  iron  and  steel  subgroup  was  as  follows: 

Let  gi,  52,  •  .  ■,  Q\y  ■  ■  ■,  ?N,  represent  the  quantity  of  output  of  the  various 

products  included  in  the  index;  q\  is  the  output  of  iron  and  steel; 

and  Wi,  Wi,  .  .  .,  Wi  .  .  .,  w>n  are  the  corresponding  fixed  weights. 

Thus  the  value  of  the  index  of  manufacturing  output  in  any  year,  D,  is: 

N 

(1)  Md=-n — XlOO 

where  g'ji' is  the  output  of  the  item  i  in  the  year  D,  and  Yz  {q{^^^^ -\- q-,^^'^* -\- q-^'>'^)  is 
the  average  output  of  the  item  i  for  the  three  base  period  years,  1923  to  1925. 

Similarly,  the  value  of  the  output  index  for  the  iron  and  steel  subgroup  for  any 
year  D  is 

/o\  T gi""^i vinn 

Thus  the  value  of  the  index  of  manufacturing  output  with  the  iron  and  steel 
subgroup  removed  for  any  year  D  is: 


101 

(3)  Md'  = 


of  '^qPwi  j-giDu)iX  100 


r>^X)wi(9i*"'2'  +  gi""  +  9i"")  )-%  «^i(gi""  +  gi»24  4-gii«5) 
Formula  (3)  may  be  rewritten: 

N 
MDX)/3Xl"'i(g,""  +  gil«4  +  gim5)  _/pX/»  «^l((7l"2Hgi""  +  gi"") 

(4)        M^'=  '-' ^ 

(  HX)"'i('/""  +  ?'""  +  9'"'")  )-^  u;i(gi"w+gi"»  +  gi'»") 


'  For  a  description  of  the  Federal  Reserve  Board's  Indexes  of  production  see  the  mimeographed  release  of 
the  Division  of  Research  and  Statistics,  Federal  Reserve  Board,  "Federal  Reserve  Index  of  Industrial 
Production."  reprinted  from  the  Fderal  Reserve  Bulletin  for  February  and  March,  1927,  with  notes  on  sub- 
sequent revisions.    (Release  dated  Nov.,  1937.) 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13935 


The  value  of  Ys'^Wi  (3ii»2'  +  gi>92<  +  gii»")  =  60,639,571  and  the  value  of  }i  Wi 
(?i""  +  3i"2^  +  qi"")  =  13,937,195.2 


(5) 


Thus  formula  (4)  may  be  written: 

A/d  X  (0.060640)  -/pX  (0.013937) 
0.046703 


Md'  =  - 


u       nn.c^no-  w    60,639,571-13,937,195 

where  0.046703  is  equal  to  1,000,000,600' 

The  details  of  the  computation  are  shown  below  in  Table  A-6. 

Table  A-6. — Computation   of  Federal   Reserve    Board   Index   of   Manufacturing 
Production  Excluding  Iron  and  Steel,  1919-1938 

[1923-1925  =  100] 


Year 

M 

(1) 

Ms 
0.060640 

(2) 

I 
(3) 

Ix 

0.013937 

(4) 

(2) -(4) 
(5) 

M 

(5)X 

0.046703 

(6) 

1919.... 

84 
87 
67 
86 
101 
94 
105 
108 
106 
llS 
119 
95 
80 
63 
75 
78 
90 
105 
109 
84 

5.094 
5.276 
4.063 
6.215 
6.125 
5.700 
6.367 
6.549 
6.428 
6.792 
7.216 
5.761 
4.851 
3.820 
4.548 
4.730 
5.458 
6.367 
6.610 
5.094 

82 
99 
46 
82 
105 

106 
113 
104 
119 
130 
94 
60 
31 
53 
60 
79 
HO 
118 
66 

1.143 
1.380 
0.641 
1.143 
1.464 
1.241 
1.478 
1.575 
1.450 
1.659 
1.812 
1.310 
0.836 
0.432 
0.739 
0.836 
1.101 
1.533 
1.645 
0.920 

3.951 
3.896 
3.422 
4.072 
4.661 
4.459 

4.974 
5.978 
5.133 
5.404 
4.451 
4.015 
3.388 
3.809 
3.894 
4.357 
4.834 
4.965 
4.174 

85 

1920 

83 

1921 

73 

1922 

87 

1923 

100 

1924 

95 

1925 

105 

1926 

107 

1927 

107 

1928  . 

110 

1929 

116 

1930 

95 

1931 

86 

1932 

73 

1933 

82 

1934 

83 

1935                                    

93 

1936    . 

104 

1937     .. 

106 

1938 ..     . 

89 

Sources: 

Col.  (1):  Federal  Reserve  Index  of  Production:  Manufactures.    See  footnote  2  in  text.  ■ 

Col.  (2):  Column  (1)  multiplied  by  0.060640. 

Col.  (3):  The  subgroup  index  for  iron  and  steel  production.    See  footnote  2  in  text. 

Col.  (4):  Column  (3)  multiplied  by  0.013937. 

Col.  (5):  Column  (2)  minus  column  (4). 

Col.  (6):  Index  of  Production:  Manufactures  excluding  iron  and  steel. 

Appendix  VII. — Demand  Relation  Equations 

Let  Xp   denote  the  quantity  of  production  of  steel  ingots  and  castings   (in  thou- 
sands of  gross  tons), 
Zb,  the  quantity  of  steel  bookings  (in  thousands  of  gross  and  net  tons), 
Xa,  the  quantity  of  steel  shipments  (in  thousands  of  gross  and  net  tons), 
p,  the  Iron  Age  composite  price  of. finished  steel  (in  cents  per  pound), 
/,  the  index  of  industrial  production  excluding  iron  and  steel  (1923-1925  = 

100), 
/„  the  link  relatives  of  /, 

S,  supernumerary  income  (in  biUions  of  dollars), 
P,  industrial  profits  (in  billions  of  dollars), 
and  t,  Time  (in  years  measured  from  an  origin  depending  on  the  period  studied). 

»  These  figures  were  obtained  from  Mr.  F.  A.  Ooldenweiser,  Director  of  Research  and  Statistics,  of  the 
Division  of  Research  and  Statistics  of  the  Board  of  Governors  of  the  Federal  Reserve  System  in  a  letter  dated 
June  29,  1939. 


13936        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Then  the  four  relations  stated  on  page  24  may  be  stated  mathematically  in  the 
form: 

Relation  I:      Xp—ap  +  b^p  +  c^I+dJ 
Relation  II:     2;p=ep+/p7)  +  gp/-|-/ip/r 
Relation  III:  x,=a,+b,p  +  c^S  +  d,P+e^t 
Relation  IV:   Xb  =  ab  +  bbP  +  CbS  +  dbP+ebt 

A  fifth  relation  also  was  studied. 

Relation  V:  Xp=Ap^I°10'>*' 

The  various  constants,  Cp,  bp,  etc.,  were  determined  by  the  method  of  least 
squares.     The  resulting  statistical  demand  relations  are  shown  below  in  Table  A-7. 

Table  A-7. — Equations  of  Demand  Relations 


Period  Studied 

Relation 
Number 

Equation  of  Demand  Relation 

1919-1938'  .___ 

1919-1938'.  .._. 

•1922-1938' 

•1920-1938.. 

1919-1938* 

•1922-1938* 

1919-1938* 

•1922-1938* 

1922-1938* 

I 
I 
I 

n 
m 
in 

IV 
IV 

V 

ip= -63,800+7,478  p+893  7-91.1  t 

ip 65,200+8.201  p+890  / 

Xo 57,081+2.217  p+944  7-127  t 

ip=»-71,700+8,605  p+857  7+87  I, 
.T.=3,014+388  p+1,005  P+510  .?+144  t 
!.= 11, 760-2,419  p+1,157  P+426  S+59  t 
Jb  =8,680+298  p+1,563  P+327  -S+270  t 
Zb=33,480-10,254  p+1,863  P+258  S+143  t 
0.158  p""'  72Mr 

100.00201 

1  Origin  of  time  variable  is  January  1, 1929. 

•  Time  variable  has  been  excluded  in  the  equation. 

•  Origin  of  time  variable  is  January  1, 1929. 

•  Origin  of  time  variable  is  July  1, 1930. 
•Equations  used  in  text  Tables  1  and  2. 

Given  these  equations,  it  is  a  simple  task  to  measure  the  elasticity  of  demand, 
or  the  elasticity  of  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  with  respect  to  thfe  price  of  steel. 
Let  Xc  be  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  as  computed  from  one  of  the  above  equations. 

dxc  p 

Then  the  elasticity  of  demand  is  equal  to . .     Thus  the  elasticity  of 

dp  Xo 

demand  formula  for  the  first  of  the  above  equations  is  (where  e  denotes  elasticity 
of  demand) : 

7,478  p 

(a)  e= 

-63,800  +  7,478  p  +  893  7-91.1  t 

The  elasticity  formulae  for  the  other  equations  are  similarly  defined,  except  for 
Relation  V,  which  is  directly 

e  =  0.235 

It  is  obvious  therefore  that,  with  the  exception  of  Relation  V,  the  elasticity  is 
not  constant,  but  varies  with  the  factors  influencing  demand. 

In  Table  2,  the  elasticities  were  computed  by  substituting  the  average  values  of 
the  demand  factors  in  equations  such  as  that  above. 

Appendix  VIII.  Definition  and  Measurement  of  the  Economic  Variables 

Used 

(1)  The  Quanliljj  of  Sted  Sold. — The  "quantity  of  steel  feold"  has  been  defined 
on  a  previous  page  '  as  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  by  steel  producers.  There  are 
two  major  problems  in  the  measurement  of  the  quantity  of  steel  sold: 

(a)  No  reliable  data  are  available  showing  for  the  country  as  a  whole  the 
physical  quantity  of  steel  sold,  either  as  a  gross  figure  or  by  separate  types  of 
steel. 

(b)  As  was  emphasized  in  section  III-A,  even  if  sales  figures  for  the  separate 
types  of  steel  were  available,  there  would  still  remain  the  problem  of  com- 
bining them  into  an  economically  logical  composite  representing  the  total 

>  Seenipra,  p.  11. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13937 

physical  volume  of  sales.  It  should  be  obvious  that  the  various  types  of  steel 
do  not  have  the  same  economic  importance  (in  a  demand  analysis)  per  pound. 
Furthermore,  the  demand  conditions  for  the  different  types  of  steel  need  not 
(and,  in  general  will  not)  be  the  same.  Moreover,  the  types  of  steel  tend  to 
change  in  character  from  year  to  year.  The  problem  of  finding  some  common 
unit  by  which  different  items  could  be  aggregated  is  one  for  which  a  thoroughly 
satisfactory  solution  has  never  been  reached.''  In  the  absence  of  an  answer 
to  the  problem,  the  only  recourse  is  to  adopt  the  usual  aggregating  proce- 
dures used  in  making  index  numbers.  It  seems  doubtful  that  this  will  result 
in  damagingly  spurious  information. 

Six  sets  of  data  have  been  considered  here  in  estimating  the  quantity  of  steel 
sold. 

(i)  Production  of  steel  ingots  and  castings  in  the  United  States  as  reported  by 
the  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute.'  These  figures  have  the  advantage, 
as  a  proxy  measure  of  the  quantity  of  steel  sold,  of  representing  almost  com- 
plete coverage  of  the  production  of  steel  ingots  and  castings  in  the  United 
States.  The  main  disadvantage  is  that  steel  ingot  production  at  best  can 
represent  only  finished  steel  production  and  not  finished  steel  sales.  Sales 
differ  from  production  by  the  amount  of  the  net  change  in  inventories  of  steel 
in  the  hands  of  steel  producers.  At  times  of  rapid  economic  change,  the 
fluctuations  of  these  inventories  are  probably  substantial  enough  seriously  to 
invalidate  the  use  of  production  figures.  Since  there  are  no  complete  or 
reliable  figures  available  showing  the  net  change  in  steel  inventories  in  the 
hands  of  producers,  no  adjustments  can  be  made  in  the  production  figures. 

(ii)  Production  of  hot-rolled  iron  and  steel  in  the  United  States.  These., 
figures  are  reported  by  the  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute  both  as  a  total 
figure  in  gross  tons,  and  by  separate  gross-ton  totals  for  about  twenty  differ- 
ent types  of  hot-rolled  iron  and  steel. ^     The  advantages  of  these  figures  are 

(a)  They  represent  practically  complete  coverage  of  hot-rolled  iron 
and  steel  production  in  the  United  States. 

(b)  They  are  more  nearly  representative  of  finished  steel  than  ingot 
production  figures. « 

(c)  The  breakdown  into  separate  types  makes  it  possible  to  weight 
the  various  types  and  thus  obtain  a  more  logical  measure  of  finished 
steel  output.  However,  these  figures  have  the  same  disadvantage  as 
steel  ingot  production  figures,  namely,  that  they  are  production  and  not 
sales  figures,  and  thus  will  be  in  error  by  the  amount  of  net  change  in 
hot-rolled  iron  and  steel  inventories  in  the  hands  of  steel  producers. 

(iii)  Index  of  Production:  Steel  Works  and  Rolling  Mills  computed  by  the 
National  Research  Project  of  the  Works  Progress  Administration.*  The 
main  advantage  of  the  series  is  that  an  attempt  was  made  to  combine  the 
different  types  of  steel  on  the  basis  of  a  measure  of  their  economic  importance. 
The  series,  however,  has  two  substantial  disadvantages: 

(a)  The  production  composite  was  computed  for  use  in  a  study  of 
labor  productivity  in  the  steel  industry.  Thus  the  economic  weights 
used-^although  perhaps  satisfactory  for  a  productivity  study — have 
practically  no  relation  to  the  economic  importance  of  the  different  types 
of  steel  from  the  point  of  view  of  steel  demand  analysis. 

2  See.  for  example,  the  excellent  discussion  in  J.  D.  Black  and  B.  D.  Mudeett,  Research  H  Agricultural 
Index  Nvmhers,  (Social  Science  Research  Council,  Bulletin  10)  1938,  and  the  sources  quoted  therein. 

3  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute,  Annual  Statistical  Report  for  19iS,  1939,  p.  16.  Th'-sc  figures  are  re- 
ported in  total  and  by  types  on  a  gross  ton  basis.  Five  types  of  steel  ingots  are  included  (basic  and  acid 
open-hearth,  hcssemer,  electric,  and  crucible).  In  1934  and  subsequent  years  the  total  for  steel  ingots  and 
castings  included  only  that  portion  of  the  production  of  steel  for  castings  used  by  foundries  operated  by  com- 
panies producing  steel  ingots. 

Figures  comparable  to  those  of  the  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute  were  also  available  for  the  United 
States  Steel  Corporation. 

*  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute,  Annual  Stalistical  Report  for  193S,  pp.  21-23,  and  Annual  Statistical 
Report  for  19S7,  p.  22. 

The  following  classification  of  hot -rolled  iron  and  steel  is  made:  plates;  sheets;  strip;  black  plate;  hoops; 
cotton  ties  and  baling  bands;  merchant  bars;  concrete  bars;  structural  shapes;  sheet  piling;  rails;  long  splice 
bars  and  tie-plate  bars;  skelp;  wire  rods;  rolled  forging  billets;  cross  ties;  blooms,  billets,  etc.,  for  export; 
strip  and  sheets  for  cold-reduced  black  plate  and  tin-plate  (separate  classification  only  for  1938);  blanks  or 
pierced  billets  for  seamless  tubes  (separate  classification  beginning  in  1926);  rolled  steel  car  wheels  (separate 
classification  beginning  in  1931) ;  and  all  other.  Inasmuch  as  production  of  hot-rolled  iron  amounts  (in  most 
years,  1919  to  1938)  to  less  than  3  or  4  percent  of  the  total,  and  since  its  fluctuations  correspond  closely  to  those 
of  hot-rolled  steel,  the  above  figures  are  very  close  approximations  of  hot-rolled' steel  production.  There  is 
a  separate  total  for  hot-roIIcd  steel  production,  but  no  breakdown  into  separate  types  of  products. 

•  In  fact,  a  large  proportion  of  the  finished  steel  sold  is  hot-rolled  steel. 

'  Works  Progress  Administration,  National  Research  Project,  Production.  Employment,  and  Productijily 
in  69  Manufacturing  Industries  (Report  No.  S-1),  Pt.  II,  May,  1939,  pp.  92-100.  A  detailed  description  of 
the  methods  used  in  constructing  the  index  is  given. 


13938        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(b)  They  are  production  and  not  sales  figures, 
(iv)  Estimates  of  finished  steel  shipments  by  The  Iron  Age  and  Steel,  two 
leading  steel  trade  journals.'  In  each  case  the  estimates  are  based  on  reports 
from  steel  producers.  The  estimates  purport  to  show  the  total  volume  of 
shipments  of  finished  steel  by  separate  types  of  steel  to  major  consuming 
industries.     Although  these  estimates  have  the  obvious  advantages: 

(a)  The  breakdown  of  the  total  into  subtotals  by  separate  types  of 
steel  and  by  consuming  industries  makes  possible  the  computation  of  a 
logical  economic  composite  measure, 

(b)  They  are  estimates  of  sales  of  finished  steel  and  not  of  production 
of  steel, 

their  unreliability  was  too  great  to  warrant  using  them.  The  coverage  of 
the  series  was  low  until  recently,  and  varied  considerably  from  year  to 
year.  Moreover,  the  classification  of  types  of  steel  and  consuming  indus- 
tries was  not  the  same  from  year  to  year  so  that  it  was  difficult  to  make  use 
of  the  sub-group  totals.        : 

(v)  United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries'  domestic  shipments  of  rolled 
and  finished  steel  products.  Inasmuch  as  steel  production  and  sales  of  the 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  have  since  1919  comprised  one- 
third  to.one-half  of  the  total  for  the  country  as  a  whole  it  was  thought  possible 
to  estimate  the  nation's  sales  from  those  of  the  Corporation  subsidiaries. 
The  series  have  the  obvious  disadvantage  that  they  represent  only  sales  of 
the  United  States  Steel  Corporation.  Although  the  types  of  steel  sold  by 
the  Corporation  do  not  represent  exactly  the  composite  type  for  the  industry 
as  a  whole,  and  though  the  conditions  of  demand  for  the  United  States  Steel 
Corporation  subsidiaries  are  not  identical  to  those  for  the  industry  it  was 
decided  that  these  disadvantages  were  not  great  enough  to  preclude  use  of 
the  figures.     The  series  does  have  several  important  advantages. 

(a)  Its  coverage  is  reasonably  well  defined  in  relation  to  the  industry 
as  a  whole. 

(b)  Only  domestic  shipment^  are  included.  Thus  no  adjustment  for 
exports  is  needed. 

(c)  The  figures  represent  sales  and  not  production. 

(vi)  United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries'  domestic  customers'  book- 
ings of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products.  These  data  consist  of  aU  domestic 
contracts  for  tonnage.  They  have  the  same  disadvantages  as  the  above  ship- 
ment figures,  but  they  do  have  one  important  advantage  over  the  shipm.ent 
figures.  Since  there  is  some  lag  between  the  time  an  order  (booking)  is  placed 
and  the  time  shipment  is  made,8  the  shipment  figures  do  not  coincide  in  time 
with  the  demand  conditions  under  which  the  order  is  placed  and  the  sale 
made. 

It  was  finally  decided  that  three  of  the  above  six  sets  of  data  would  not 
prove  useful  in  estimating  the  quantity  of  steel  sold: 

(a)  The  Iron  Age  and  Steel  estimates  of  finished  steel  shipments,  be- 
cause they  were  considered  too  unreliable. 

(b)  The  W.  P.  A.  National  Research  Project  index  of  steel  works  out- 
put because  it  was  a  production  index,  and  because  its  construction  was 
not  deemed  suitable  for  a  demand  study. 

(c)  Production  of  hot-rolled  iron  and  steel,  because  it  followed  steel 
iugot  production  so  closely  '  that  it  possessed  no  great  advantage  over 
the  latter."" 

Three  separate  estimates  of  the  quantity  of  steel  sold  were  used  for  further 
experimentation: 

(a)  The  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute  figures  on  production  of 
steel  ingots  and  castings  were  used  directly  as  representing  sales.  These 
figures  were  considered  as  the  least  satisfactory  of  the  three  estimates. 
However,  it  was  decided  to  use  them  because  of  thfeir  greater  familiarity. 


'  In  connection  with  this  section  see  the  detailed  discussion  in  the  memorandum  of  M.  W.  Worthing, 
"Distribution  of  Steel  Products  to  Major  C  insuming  Industries,"  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  October 
30.  1939. 

•  This  lag  varies  greatly  with  the  rate  of  operations  and  the  order  backlog  of  steel  producers.  For  example 
at  the  peak  of  the  boom  in  1937  shipments  on  some  products  were  delayed  for  as  much  as  six  to  seven  months 
after  the  placing  of  the  order 

•  The  year  to  year  fluctuations  in  steel  ingot  production  were  almost  identical  to  those  of  hot-rolled  iron 
and  steel  production  except  for  a  long-run  smooth  trend  increase  in  the  ratio  of  the  former  to  the  latter. 
See  chart  A. 

'•  Preliminary  experimentation  Indicated  that  no  improvement  would  be  madp  by  computing  a  composite 
measure  in  which  the  dIfTerent  types  of  hot-rolled  iron  and  steel  were  given  weights  corresponding  to  their 
respective  prices.- 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13939 

(b)  A  second  estimate  was  based  on  the  United  States  Steel  Corpora- 
tion subsidiaries'  figures  for  total  shipments  of  rolled  and  finished  steel. 
The  estimate  was  made  in  the  following  simple  manner.  It  was  assumed 
that  for  any  year  the  ratio  of  the  Corporation  subsidiaries'  shipments 
to  those  of  the  industry  as  a  whole  was  the  same  as  the  ratio  of  the 
Corporation  subsidiaries'  production  of  steel  ingots  and  castings  to  that 
for  the  industry.  Estimated  total  shipments  were  thus  obtained  by 
dividing  the  Corporation  subsidiaries'  total  shipments  by  the  latter  of 
the  above  two  ratios. 
This  procedure  was  justified  on  these  grounds: 

(i)  There  is  very  little  time  lag  between  ingot  production  and  actual 
shipment. 

(ii)  It  seemed  reasonable  to  believe  that  the  Corporation  subsidiaries 
weight  losses  (conversion  losses)  involved  in  converting  steel  ingots  into 
finished  steel  were  not  substantially  different  from  those  for  the  industry 

Chart  A 


80 
72 
64 
56 

i  "" 

g     40 

i     32 
o 
.     24 

S 

8 
\ 

STEEL   PRODUCTION 

IN  UNITED  STATES 

72 
64 
56 

48    2 
40    ? 
32     i 

24     I 
16     1 

i 
8 

/ 

X' 

V 

Gor 

»ST 

AN 

•) 

^ 

y 

\ 

/ 

'^ 

\ 

NGS 

1 

/ 

\ 

1 

/ 

s^ 

/I 

x' 

\ 

\ 

/ 

^ 

/ 

\\ 

/ 

/ 

\ 

HOT 

f] 

«3N 

ROL 
>IISH 
AND 

LED 

-D 

STCE 

\\ 

y 

r 

/ 

' 

Y 

/ 

1 

L 

\ 

\ 

/ 

/ 

/ 

\ 

/ 

5  1  i  1  i  i  s  1  i  1  i  1  1  i  i  i  § 

\  \ 

\  1  \ 

1 1  \ 

as  a  whole,  or,  at  least,  that  the  ratio  of  the  Corporation  subsidiaries' 
weight  losses  to  those  of  the  industry  did  not  change  sharply  from  year 
to  year. 

(iii)  The  ratio  of  the  Corporation  subsidiaries'"  steel  ingot  production 
to  that  of  the  industry  was  almost  constant  except  for  a  smooth  long  run 
decline, 
(c)   A  third  estimate  was  based  on  the  United   States   Steel   Corporation 
subsidiaries'  figures  for  domestic  bookings  of  rolled  and  finished  steel. 

The  method  of  adjusting  this  series  "was  the  same -as  that  used  for  the  Cor- 
poration subsidiaries'  shipments. 

The  above  three  estimates  are  shown  on  Chart  1,  page  21,  and  in  Appendix 
I,  Table  A-1.  The  details  of  the  estimations  of  bookings  and  shipments 
are  shown  in  Appendix  II. 

(2)    The  Price  of  Steel. — The  difficulties  of  defining  and  measuring  the  price  of 
steel  were  indicated  in  sections  III- A,  and  III-F: 

(a)  There  are  many  different  kinds  of  finished  steel  sold,  and  ^each  kind 
has  its  own  price.  Thus  there  is  a  problem  similar  to  that  encountered  in 
defining  and  measuring  the  quantity  of  steel  sold.  How  should  the  different 
types  be  combined  in  order  to  obtain  an  economically  logical  measure  of  the 


13940  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

price  of  steel?  No  absolutely  conclusive  answer  to  this  question  has  ever 
been  given."  However,  since  the  prices  of  the  different  types  of  steel  move 
more  or  less  closely  together  a  fairly  satisfactory  solution  can  be  obtained 
by  one  of  the  well  known  averaging  methods  used  in  constructing  price 
index  numbers. 

(b)  Prices  tend  to  be  different  in  different  geographical  regions.  The 
problem  here  is  essentially  the  same  as  the  first. 

(c)  Because  of  price  concessions,  published  prices — which  are  the  only 
source  of  price  data — do  not  always  reflect  the  actual  prices  paid  by  steel 
buyers. 

There  are  three  well  known  series  computed  for  the  composite  price  of 
finished  steel : 

(i)  That  computed  by  Iron  Age. 

(ii)  That  computed  by  Steel. 

(iii)  That  computed  by  the  American  Metal  Market. 

(i)  The  Iron  Age  Composite  Price  of  Finished  Steel  is  published 
weekly  in  Iron  Age.^^  The  Iron  Age  composite  is  a  simple  un- 
weighted arithmetic  average  of  the  following  items:  bars,  plates, 
shapes,  hot-rolled  strip,  plain  wire,  heavy  rails,  black  pipe,  and 
No.  10  gage  hot- rolled  sheets. '^  The  prices  used  in  each  case  are 
the  Iron  Age  weekly  market  quotations  of  base  prices  at  Pitts- 
burgh." The  quotations  are  based  on  the  Iron  Age  estimate  as 
to  what  is  the  "open  market  price."  '^ 

(ii)  Steel's  composite  price  of  finished  steel  is  based  on  weekly 
steel  price  quotations  as  reported  by  Steel.  The  composite  is  a 
simple  unweighted  arithmetic  average  of  the  prices  at  Pittsburgh 
of  the  following  items:  plates,  shapes,  bars,  wide  hot- rolled  strip, 
wire  nails,  plain  wire,  tin  plate,  black  pipe.  No.  24  gage  hot-rolled 
sheets,  and  No.  24  gage  galvanized  sheets."  The  weekly  quotations 
on  which  the  composite  is  based  represent  the  best  judgment  of  the 
editors  of  Steel  as  to  the  going  market  prices. '^ 

(iii)  The  American  Metal  Market  composite  price  of  finished  steel 
is  based  on  daily  price  quotations  published  in  the  American  Metal 
Market.^^  The  composite  is  a  weighted  arithmetic  average  of  the 
following  finished  steel  products:  bars,  plates,  shapes,  pipe,  wire 
nails.  No.  24  gage  sheets,  strips,  and  tin-plate.'^ 
The  three  composites  are  so  similar  in  their  movements  as  to  make  a 
choice   between   them   unimportant.     The   Iron  Age   composite   price   was 

>i  J.  D.  Black  and  B.  D.  Mndpett.-op.  :il.    See  footnote  2  of  this  appendix. 

12  Annual  and  monthly  averages  for  the  yeans  1903  to  1938  are  given  in  the  /ron  ^fff,  Jan.  5, 1939,  pp  198-199. 

13  Hot-rolled  strip  was  not  included  prior  to  1920.  Before  1920  No.  24  gage  hot-rolled  annealed  sheets  is 
used  instead  of  No.  10  gage  hot-rolled  sheets.    (Information  from  letter  cited  in  footnote  15.) 

1*  Although  steel  prices  vary  from  one  geographical  area  to  another  (see  section  III-F.),  the  year  to  year 
fluctuations  in  all  areas  tend  to  he  more  or  less  the  same.  Thus  it  is  doubtful  if  there  is  any  serious  unrepre- 
sentativeness  in  a  composite  based  on  Pittsburgh  prices. 

i»  Mr.  C.  E.  Wright,  Managing  Editor  of  Iron  Age,  in  a  letter  dated  April  5,  1939,  writes:  "We  do  not 
change  our  base  prices  unless  we  feel  tliat  such  a  change  has  become  more  or  less  general.  For  example,  when 
a  break  in  sheet  prices  occurred  in  October,  1938,  we  did  not  reduce  our  base  price  on  the  first  news  that  a 
concession  had  been  made  to  one  or  two  companies,  but  the  following  week,  however,  this  concession  had 
become  general.  That  is,  all  companies  were  making  it  to  all  customers,  and  therefore  it  became  an  open 
market  price." 

1'  This  description  of  the  Steel  composite  price  was  obtained  from  Mr.  O.  H.  Manlove,  Associate  Editor 
of  Steel  in  a  letter  dated  April  12,  1939.  Prior  to  July,  1938,  the  price  of  No.  28  gage  rather  than  of  No.  24 
gage  galvanized  sheets  was  used  in  the  composite.  After  April,  1938,  the  editors  of  Steel  added  an  extra 
of  90  cents  to  the  quotation  for  No.  24  hot-rolled  sheets.  Annual  and  monthly  figures  for  the  composite  for 
the  years  1927  to  1938  are  given  in  Steel,  Jan.  2,  1939,  p.  251. 

"  Mr.  Manlove  writes:  .  .  "the  quoted  prices  are  the  best  judgment  of  the  editors  [of  Steel],  although  in 
the  present  market  procedure  with  prices  announced  by  quarters,  there  is  comparatively  little  variation 
from  the  published  figures."  .     , ,     , 

1'  Annual  figures  from  1899  to  1937,  and  monthly  figures  for  the  years  1914  to  1937  are  shown  In  Metal 
Statistics  for  19S8,  published  by  the  American  Metal  Market  Company,  1939,  pp.  85-88.  Recent  figures 
can  be  obtained  from  current  issues  of  the  American  Metal  Market,  metal  trades  dally  paper. 

'»  The  weights  are  as  follows: 

Aars - - ■- - - 2.0 

Plates - - 1-5 

Shapes - -  10 

Pipe(l-3) - - - - - 1-6 

wire  nails - — - }-0 

Sheets 1-6 

Strips. - - JO 

Tin  plate- - _0-j 

Total - 10.0 

These  weights  are  rough  estimates  of  the  "relative  Importance"  of  the  different  Items.     Prior  to  Mar. 
29, 1033,  another  system  of  weights  was  used.    See  Metal  Statistics  for  19S8,  p.  85,  and  for  1932,  p.  21. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13941 

selected  for  use  in  the  statistical  analysis  because  it  was  the  most  widely 
known  of  the  three. 

(3)  Consumers'  Cash  Income.^" — The  measure  of  consumer  income  which 
seemed  most  appropriate  for  the  purpose  of  this  paper,  was  one  measuring  the 
actual  amount  of  cash  income  received  by  consumers  and  disposable  by  them  for 
consumers'  goods  and  services.  The  two  basic  series  which  most  closely  approxi- 
mate this  ideal  measure  are: 

(a)  The   United  States   Department  of   Commerce  series  for  "national 
income  payments."  ^^ 

(b)  The  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research  series  for  "aggrecate 
income  payments  to  individuals"  (basic  variant)  .^^ 

Neither  of  these  series  is  completely  appropriate;  both  include  payment  items 
not  actually  received  by  consumers  and  exclude  certain  other  items  that  are 
received  by  consumers.*'  However,  both  series  are  reasonably  good  estimates  of 
cash  payments  to  consumers. 

Inasmuch  as  the  United  States  Department  of  Commerce  series  does  not  go 
back  beyond  1929,  the  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research  estimates  were 
used  for  the  years  1919  to  1928.  The  latter  series  was  linked  to  the  former 
at  1929." 

(4)  The  Cost  of  Living.^^ — The  majority  of  consumers'  products-made-from- 
steel — of  which  the  passenger  automobile  is  most  important— are  luxury  goods 
which  can  be  thought  of  as  being  purchased  with  that  part  of  consumers'  cash 
income  remaining  after  the  necessary  or  subsistence  costs  of  living  have  been 
paid.  It  is  obviously  unrealistic — as  well  as  difficult — to  draw  a  hard  and  fast 
line  at  what  can  be  called  subsistence  living  costs,  and  to  assume  that  only  after 
such  costs  are  met  can  the  consumer  begin  buying  luxury  goods.  But  on  the 
average  some  such  relationship  exists. 

The  subsistence  costs  of  living  per  person  were  taken  as  $225.82  for  the  month 
of  March,  1935.  This  is  equivalent  to  the  $903.27  which  the  Works  Progress 
Administration  set  up  as  the  minimum  costs  of  living  for  a  family  of  four  in 
March,  1935.2^  For  other  periods  the  subsistence  costs  of  living  were  assumed 
to  vary  from  this  level  as  did  the  National  Industrial  Conference  Board  index 
of  the  cost  of  living  vary  from  its  March,  1935,  level.*'  After  computing  sub- 
sistence costs  of  living  for  the  country  as  a  whole,  subsistence  living  costs  were 
subtracted  from  consumers'  cash  income,  leaving  consume? s'  supernumerary 
income.^^  Supernumerary  income,  or  the  amount  of  cash  income  disposable  for 
luxury  goods  and  services,  was  the  income  series  used  in  the  statistical  analysis. 
The  series  is  shown  in  Chart  1.  and  Appendix  I. 

(5)  Industrial  Profits.^^ — The  basic  sources  of  data  on  industrial  profits  are  re- 
ports received  by  the  United  States  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue  from  all  com- 
panies filing  Federal  corporation  income  and  excess  profits  tax  returns  and  per- 
sonal holding  company  returns.  These  reports  are  compiled  and  published 
annually  in  the  Bureau's  Statistics  of  Income  reports.^'^  The  profit  figures  which 
were  used  in  this  study  were  based  on  these  Statistics  of  Income  reports,^'  and  were 
computed  from  the  following  formula: 

Industrial  profits  equal 

Statutory  net  income  ** 

"  In  connection  with  this  section  see  Roos  and  von  Szelislci,  op.  cit.,  pp.  39-41. 

"  Robert  R.  Nathan,  "Income  In  the  United  States,  192&-37"  (Bulletin  of  the  United  States  Department 
of  Commerce,  Nov.,  1938);  "National  Income  in  1938  at  64  Billion  Dollars,"  Survey  of  Current  Business. 
June,  1939,  p.  12;  Frederick  M.  Cone,  "Revised  Estimates  of  Monthly  Income  Payments  in  the  United 
States,  1929  to  1938",  Surrey  of  Current  Business,  October,  1938,  p.  15. 

"  Simon  Kuznets,  National  Income  and  Capital  Formation,  1919-1986,  National  Bureau  of  Economic 
Research,  1937. 

2'  See  the  discussions  in  the  sources  cited  in  footnotes  20  to  22. 

»<  Certain  revisions,  however,  were  first  made  in  the  Department  of  Commerce  series;  see  Appendix  III. 

"  See  Roos  and  von  Szeliski,  op.  cit.,  pp.  41-42. 

>'  Works  Progress  Administration,  Division  of  Social  Research,  "Intercity  Differences  in  Costs  of  Living 
in  March,  1935,  .59  Cities"  (Research  Monograph  XII). 

"  A  detailed  description  of  this  index  is  presented  in  The  Cost  of  Livinfi  in  the  United  States,  191i-]9S6, 
pp.  13-42,  published  by  the  National  Industrial  Conference  Board.  Monthly  and  annual  figures  are 
reported  in  the  Survey  of  Current  Business,  19S8  Supplement,  p.  11,  and  current  issues. 

"  The  details  of  the  computation  of  supernumerary  income  are  given  in  Appendix  IV. 

"  In  connection  with  the  discussion  of  this  section  see  W.  L.  Crum.  "Corporate  Earnings  on  Invested 
Capital",  Harvard  Business  Review,  v.  XVI,  No.  3,  pp.  336  to  350. 

"  United  States  Treasury  Department,  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue,  Statistics  of  Income  for  1938,  1939, 
Part  II,  and  for  previous  years. 

n  The  Statistics  of  Income  reports  represent  almost  complete  coveraee  of  business  profits.  The  number  of 
business  concerns  not  filing  returns  under  the  various  Federal  revenue  acts  do  a  negligible  proportion  of  the 
nation's  business. 

"  Statistics  of  Income  for  19S6,  p.  47.    Statutory  net  income  represents  "net  income  less  deficit."    In  other 

S laces  it  is  called  simply  "net  income";  see,  for  example,  p.  24.    For  1936  and  1937  statutory  net  income 
icludea  "dividends  received  from  domestic  corporations." 


13942  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

less      The  total  federal  tax  ^J 

plus     Tax-exempt  interest  on  government  obligations  " 

less      Dividends  received  from  domestic  corporations  (for  1936  and  1937)." 

What  was  desired  was  a  series  showing  for  any  year  the  real  (economic)  profit 

situation,  and  thus  the  current  real  profit  outlook  of  buyers  of  producers'  products- 

made-from-steel.     The  above  profit  figures  are  subject  to  some  severe  limitations 

in  this  respect: 

(a)  Certain  corporations  included  in  the  profit  reports  can  be  only  of  insig- 
nificant importance  as  buyers  in  the  capital  goods  market.  The  most 
important  of  these  groups  is  the  group  of  "financial"  institutions.  Total 
profits  of  this  group — and  others  not  relevant  to  the  capital  goods  market — 
however,  are  not  a  large  enough  proportion  of  the  total,  and  do  not  vary 
enough  from  the  general  movement  of  profits  to  distort  the  figures  seriously. 

(b)  A  much  more  serious  limitation  is  that  the  tax  accounting  proce- 
dures used  by  business  tend  to  make  their  profit  figures  represent  the 
profit  situation  and  outlook  of  a  period  somewhat  prior  to  that  for 
which  the  figures  are  actually  reported.  The  largest  part  of  the  receipts  of 
business  comes  from  sales  of  goods  and  services.  These  receipts  are  based  on 
current  sales  prices  more  or  less  accurately  reflecting  current  cost  and  demand 
conditions.  However,  since  production  must  precede  the  date  of  sale,  and 
since  many  of  the  costs  of  production  are  incurred  at  an  even  earlier  date 
(purchase  of  raw  materials,  equipment,  etc.),  the  cost  of  production  figures 
used  in  profit  calculations  represent  the  cost  situation  of  an  earlier  date.  If 
costs  and  prices  have  in  the  meantime  changed  drastically,  a  substantial  part 
of  the  profits  or  losses  reported  are  what  amounts  to  inventory  and  capital 
profits  or  losses.  Thus  the  profit  figures  reported  tend  to  lag  behind  the  cur- 
rent cost  and  demand  situation.  The  profit  series  used  in  this  study  is  shown 
in  Chart  1  and  Appendix  I. 

(6)  Volume  of  Industrial  Production. — The  most  widely  known  and  probably 
the  best  composite  measure  of  the  volume  of  industrial  output  is  the  Federal 
Reserve  Board's  index  of  industrial  production.*"  However,  it  has  a  very  serious 
limitation  for  the  purposes  of  this  study.  What  is  desired  is  a  measure  of  the 
industrial  production  of  all  commodities  other  than  iron  and  steel  (produced  by 
steel  producers).  Iron  and  steel  production  is  the  most  important  single  compo- 
nent of  the  Federal  Reserve  Board  index,  with  a  weight  which  gives  it  an  aggregate 
importance  of  almost  25  percent  of  the  total  for  the  index.^^  Thus  relationships 
observed  between  steel  sales  and  this  index  would  be  in  part  spurious. 

The  detailed  method  of  removing  iron  and  steel  production  from  the  index  is 
described  in  Appendix  VI.  "  The  series  with  iron  and  steel  production  removed, 
which  is  the  one  used  in  the  statistical  analysis,  is  shown  in  Chart  1  and  A  pen- 
dix  I. 


Exhibit  No.  1412 

AN  ANALYSIS  OF  CHANGES  IN  THE  DEMAND  FOR  STEEL  AND  IN 
STEEL  PRICES,  1936-1939 

This  is  an  analysis  prepared  by  the  Special  Economic  Research  Section  of 
United  States  Steel  Corporation,  composed  of  Messrs.  Edward  T.  Dickinson,  Jr., 
Ernest  M.  Doblin,  H.  Gregg  Lewis,  Jacob  L.  Mosak,  Mandal  R.  Segal,  Dwight 
B.  Yntema  and  Miss  Marion  W.  Worthing.  The  work  of  this  group  was  under 
the  supervision  of  Theodore  O.  Yntema,  Professor  of  Statistics,  University  of 
Chicago.  This  analysis  was  written  by  H.  Gregg  Lewis,  who  had  the  benefit  of 
suggestions  from  other  members  of  the  staff.  It  is  issued  by  United  States  Steel 
Corporation. 

November  1,  1939. 


M  The  total  federal  tax  Includes  the  normal  corporation  income  tax,  war  profits  and  excess  profits  taxes, 
and  the  surtax  on  undistributed  profits.    See  Statistics  of  Income  for  I9S6.  p.  47. 

"  The  amount  of  tax  exempt  interest  on  government  obligations  which  is  added  to  statutory  net  income  is 
the  amount  of  wholly  tax-exempt  interest.    See  Statistics  of  Ivcome  for  19S6,  pp.  6  and  24. 

"  In  1936  and  1937  "dividends  received  from  domestic  corporations"  were  included  in  statutory  net  Income 
for  excess  profits  tax  computation.  In  order  to  avoid  double  counting  of  corporation  earnings  it  was  there- 
fore removed.    See  footnote  32.    The  detailed  computations  of  industrial  profits  are  shown  In  .\ppendix  V. 

"  A  full  description  of  the  index  and  values  of  the  index  and  its  sub-eroups  back  to  1919  may  be  obtained 
from  the  Division  of  Research  and  Statistics  of  the  Federal  Reserve  Board,  Washington,  D.  C.  Current 
figures  are  reported  In  the  Boaras  monthly  Federal  Reseree  Bulletin,  the  Survey  of  Current  Buttness,  and 
numerous  other  places. 

•'  See  Appendix  VI.    • 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13943 

CONTENTS 

r.  Introduction 
II.  Summary  of  Findings 

III.  Nature  of  the  Demand  for  Steel 

IV.  Short  Run  Variations  in  the  Demand  for  Steel:  June  1936  to  October  1939 

A.  The  Economic  Background,  1930  to  1935 

(1)  Developments  Affecting  the  Potential  Demand  for  Producers'  Durable  Goods 

(2)  Developments  Affecting  the  Potential  Demand  for  Consumers'  Durable  Goods 

(i)  Automobiles 
(11)  Household  Furnishings 
(ill)  Residential  Construction 

(3)  Developments  in  the  Field  of  Government  Economic  Policy 

B.  The  Boom:  July  1936  to  March  1937 

(1)  Initiation  of  the  Boom— July  to  December  1936 

(a)  Developments  Affecting  the  Demand  for  Steel  by  the  Consumers'  Goods  Industries 

(1)  Automobiles 

(2)  Household  Goods 

(3)  Residential  Construction 

(b)  Developments  Affecting  the  Demand  for  Steel  by  the  Producers'  Goods  Industries 

(1)  Railroads 

(2)  Machinery  and  Equipment 

(3)  Business  Construction 

(4)  Public  Construction 

(c)  The  Behavior  of  the  Price  of  Steel 

(2)  The  Critical  Period:  January  to  March  1937 

C.  The  Decline  Begins:  April  to  September  1937 

D.  Recession:  October  1937  to  June  1938 

E.  Recovery:  June  to  December  1938 

F.  Recent  Developments:  January  to  October  1939 

G.  Conclusion 

I.  Introduction 

A  substantial  increase  in  the  level  of  steel  prices  early  in  the  spring  of  1937  was 
followed  shortly  by  a  considerable  decline  in  the  volume  of  new  orders  of  steel. 
In  June,  1938  a  drop  in  steel  prices  almost  immediately  preceded  several  months 
of  rising  sales  by  steel  makers.  Temporary  bargain  markets  for  certain  steel 
products  occurring  in  the  autumn  of  1938  and  recently  in  May  of  this  year  were 
accompanied  by  temporary  increases  in  steel  purchases. 

To  the  superficial  observer,  these  events  might  indicate  that  reductions  in  the 
price  of  steel  greatly  increase  the  tonnage  sales  and  revenues  of  steel  producers, 
and  conversely,  that  increases  in  the  level  of  steel  prices  greatly  reduce  their 
volume  of  business  and  revenues. 

The  primary  question  which  the  analysis  of  the  following  pages  will  attempt  to 
answer  is  this:  How  important  was  the  level  of  steel  prices  in  accounting  for  the 
fluctuations  in  the  demand  for  steel  that  occurred  in  the  1936-39  period?  In 
answering  this  question  it  will  be  necessary  to  examine  the  importance  of  other 
aspects  of  price  behavior,  as  well  as  the  importance  of  other  factors  which  might 
account  for  the  changes  in  demand. 

II.  Summary  of  Findings 

An  analysis  of  the  period  June  1936  to  October  1939  leads  to  several  conclusions 
with  respect  to  the  influence  of  steel  prices  on  the  quantities  of  steel  demanded  in 
the  short  run: 

(1)  Changes  in  the  levels  of  steel  buying  during  this  period  were  largely 
determined  by: 

(a)  the  current  and  anticipated  levels  of  business  activity,  income  and 
profits; 

(b)  the  expectations  with  respect  to  steel  prices  in  the  immediate 
future  as  compared  with  current  steel  prices; 

(c)  the  volume  of  steel  inventory  accumulated  in  the  immediate  past; 
and 

(d)  the  length  of  time  required  to  fill  new  orders  for  steel. 

(2)  There  is  little  evidence  that  the  actual  level  of  the  buying  price  of 
steel — within  rather  wide  limits — is  of  importance  in  explaining  the  act^'al 
level  of  steel  buying,  at  least  in  the  short  run.  That  is  to  say,  actual  changes 
in  the  price  of  steel,  per  se — apart  from  their  efl'ect  on  buyers'  expectations 
as  to  the  magnitude  and  direction  of  future  changes — are  of  minor  importance 
in  accounting  for  short  run  changes  in  the  volume  of  steel  purchases. 

To  illustrate,  the  reduction  in  new  orders  of  steel  following  shortly  after 
the  price  advances  of  March  1937,  and  the  increase  in  new  orders  which  came 
at  about  the  same  time  as  the  price  reductions  of  June  1938,  can  be  more 
reasonably  explained  by  factors  other  than  changes  in  steel  prices.  The 
great  increase  in  steel  buying  in  September  and  October  of  1939,  which 
occurred  without  reduction  in  steel  prices,  further  illustrates  the  dominant 
influence  of  factors  other  than  price  in  the  demand  for  steel. 


13944  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(3)  There  is  evidence,  however,  that  widespread  expectations  that  the  level 
of  steel  prices  is  going  to  advance  substantially  in  the  near  future  due  to 
rising  labor  and  other  costs,  and  that  the  advance  will  not  be  temporary,  will 
generally  lead  to  substantial  increases  in  the  present  volume  of  steel  buying. 
Such  anticipations  are  strengthened  if  there  have  been  price  increases  in  the 
nfear  past,  and  if  feelings  of  price  inflation  and  rising  business  activity  are 
generally  abroad  in  the  economy.  When  the  expectation  becomes  a  certainty, 
as  when  a  price  increase  is  announced  prior  to  its  effective  date,  the  effect 
will  almost  certainly  be  an  increase  in  the  level  of  buying  from  what  it  would 
otherwise  have  been. 

A  substantial  part  of  the  great  increase  in  new  orders  that  took  place  in 
the  period  November,  1936  to  March,  1937  can  be  accounted  for  by  such 
protective  forward  buying  in  advance  of  price  increases  which  had  been 
announced.  This  was  especially  true  of  the  two  months  December,  1936  and 
March,  1937  when  announcements  of  price  increases  resulted  in  a  greatly 
increased  volume  of  new  orders. 

(4)  As  a  corollary  to  the  above  point,  expectations  of  a  stable  level  of 
prices  following  a  period  of  price  advances  will  ten,d  to  reduce  the  volume 
of  buying.  That  is,  anticipations  of  stable  prices  will  tend  to  lead  to  a  lower 
volume  of  buying  than  anticipations  of  rising  prices.  Thus  the  cessation  of 
anticipated  rising  prices  will  in  general  be  accompanied  by  a  short  run  decline 
of  purchases. 

For  example,  the  decline  in  orders  in  January  and  February,  1937,  is  partly 
explained  by  the  fact  that  steel  purchasers  were  relatively  sure  that  steel 
prices  would  not  advance  much  before  April  1,  1937.  Part  of  the  decline 
in  orders  in  the  months  following  the  price  advances  of  March,  1937  can  be 
similarly  explained. 

Conversely,  expectations  of  stable  prices  following  a  period  of  falling  prices 
tend  to  increase  the  volun  i  of  steel  purchases. 

(5)  Anticipations  of  faF  ng  steel  prices  tend  to  reduce  the  amount  of  steel 
purchases  in  the  short  ru   . 

(6)  A  reduction  in  stee"  prices  that  is  expected  to  be  temporary — that  is, 
a  temporary  low  pr-ce  market  for  buyers — in  general  wiU  cause  a  short  run 
increase  of  buying.  Cases  in  point  are  the  increases  in  steel  orders  that 
took  place  in  October,  1938,  and  again  in  May,  1939. 

For  the  most  part,  the  effect  on  the  volume  of  steel  buying  of  such  price  antici- 
pation factors  as  have  been  discussed  above  is  merely  to  cause  a  short  run  shift 
in  the  date  of  actual  purchases,  without  changing  the  total  amount  bought  over 
a  twelve  or  eighteen  months'  period  from  what  it  otherwise  would  hav^  been. 
This  follows  from  the  fact  that  the  total  steel  requirements  of  steel  purchasers 
over  a  twelve  or  eighteen  months'  period  depend  very  largely  on  their  current 
and  expected  output  of  products  made  from  steel.  Increases  (or  decreases)  of  their 
inventories  of  steel  much  beyond  their  expected  production  needs  in  the  near 
future  are  both  expensive  and  risky. 

Thiis,  for  example,  short  run  heavy  buying  of  steel  in  advance  of  expected 
price  increases,  and  in  amounts  considerably  greater  than  current  production 
requirements,  is  likely  to  be  followed  by  a  substantial  short  run  drop  in  purchases. 
This  reduction  in  buying  will  be  aggravated  if  purchasers  find  their  actual  re- 
quirements smaller  than  expected,  and  thus  have  unnecessarily  large  stocks  of 
steel  on  hand.  A  considerable  part  of  the  decline  in  orders  for  steel  that  took 
place  in  the  six  or  eight  months  following  March,  1937,  can  be  accounted  for  by 
the  great  volume  of  forward  buying  between  October,  1936,  and  March,  1937, 
and  the  failure  of  actual  requirements  to  come  up  to  expectations  after  March. 

In  summary,  while  price  changes  and  anticipated  price  changes  affect  the  timing 
of  steel  purchases,  the  large  fluctuations  in  the  total  volume  of  steel  production  during 
the  1936-1939  period  cannot  be  attributed  to  changes  in  the  levels  of  steel  prices.  On 
the  contrary,  the  evidence  compels  the  conclusion  that  the  influence  of  the  level  of  steel 
prices  on  the  total  consumption  of  steel  was  relatively  unimportant. 

III.  Nature  of  the  Demand  for  Steel 

Considerations  of  central  importance  in  any  investigation  of  the  demand  for 
steel  are: 

(1)  Steel  itself  is  a  durable  commodity;  that  is,  it  may,  with  some  excep- 
tions, be  kept  in  stock  for  more  or  less  long  periods  without  serious  physical 
depreciation.  Thus  purchasers  of  steel  may  currently  buy  more  steel  than 
they  need  for  current  consumption,  building  up  a  stock  of  steel  for  future 
consumption.    Conversely,  the  building  up  oi  such  a  stock  in  the  past  enables 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13945 

a  steel  purchaser  (user  of  steel)  currently  to  buy  less  steel  than  he  consumes, 
the  balance  of  such  consumption  coming  from  depletion  of  his  steel  stock. 

The  size  of  these  inventories  will  depend  for  the  most  part  on  the  buyer's 
present  and  expected  production  requirements  of  steel,  on  his  anticipations 
regarding  near  future  prices  of  steel,  and  on  his  expectations  regarding  the 
length  of  time  it  will  take  him  to  get  delivery  on  near  future  orders  of  steel. 
If  the  steel  buyer  expects  that  prices  of  steel  shortly  will  be  higher,  or  that 
near  capacity  operations  of  steel  producers  may  delay  delivery  on  his  orders 
at  a  time  when  he  expects  his  requirements  will  be  high,  he  may  currently 
buy  more  than  he  needs  for  present  consumption,  stocking  steel  as  protection 
against  future  higher  prices  or  delivery  delay.  On  the  other  hand,  if  his 
steel  requirements  turn  out  to  be  smaller  than  expected,  he  may  find  himpelf 
with  unnecessarily  large  inventories  of  steel  on  hand,  and  thus  may  consume 
from  stock  and  curtail  his  buying.  This  will  be  expecially  true  if  the  steel 
buyer  expects  lower  steel  prices  in  the  near  future. 

However,  such  changes  in  inventories  for  the  most  part  exert  only  a  short 
run  effect  on  steel  buying,  for,  as  already  pointed  out: 

(a)  Investment  in  inventories  ties  up  capital,  and  thus  is  costly;  and 

(b)  Drastic  changes  in  inventories  are  risky;  the  buyer  must  be 
relatively  sure  of  the  near  future  course  of  prices,  and  of  his  own  pro- 
duction requirements  before  he  can  afford  to  build  up  or  deplete  his 
stock  much  out  of  line  with  his  reasonably  expected  volume  of  consump- 
tion of  steel.  Such  anticipations  are  the  more  uncertain  the  further  into 
the  future  they  extend. 

This  is  not  to  say  that  changes  in  the  size  of  steel  inventories  in  the  hands 
of  consumers  are  unimportant  in  the  short  run.  Such  changes  are  probably 
of  paramount  importance  in  explaining  the  heavy  buying  of  steel  in  the  fall 
and  winter  of  1936-37,  and  the  drastic  decline  that  followed. 

(2)  Steel  is  largely  used  in  the  production  of  durable  producers'  and 
consumers'  goods.  (1)  *  As  shown  elsewhere,  however,  the  demand  for  durable 
goods  is  particularly  subject  to  severe  cyclical  fluctuations.  It  is  to  be 
expected  that  the  demand  for  steel  should  likewise  be  severely  affected  by 
general  business  cycles,  since  the  demand  for  steel  is  ultimately  derived  from 
the  demand  for  the  services  rendered  by  durable  goods. 

(3)  The  demand  for  steel  is  inelastic.  This  means  that  a  given  percentage 
change  in  the  price  of  steel  gives  rise  to  a  smaller  percentage  change  in  the 
quantity  of  steel  demanded.     A  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel  (if  unassociated 

"with  other  factors  such  as  improving  business  conditions)  therefore  tends  to 
reduce  the  dollar  volume  of  steel  sales.  This  inelasticity  of  the  demand  for 
steel  follows  from  three  factors: 

(a)  The  low  elasticity  of  demand  for  most  of  the  finished  products 
which  are  made  from  steel; 

(b)  The  low  degree  of  substitutability  of  steel  for  other  materials  and 
of  other  materials  for  steel.  This  low  substitutability  materially  lessens 
the  responsiveness  of  the  demand  for  steel  to  the  changes  in  price;  and 

(c)  The  relatively  small  proportion  of  the  value  of  the  finished  product 
which  is  represented  by  the  cost  of  steel.  A  large  percentage  change  in 
the  price  of  steel  can  lead  to  only  a  small  percentage  change  in  the  price 
of  the  finished  product  even  if  the  entire  steel  price  reduction  is  passed 
on  to  the  final  consumer.  Since  finished  products  made  from  steel 
have,  in  general,  a  low  elasticity  of  demand,  changes  in  steel  prices,  can 
have  only  a  small  effect  on  the  output  of  finished  products,  and,  therefore, 
on  steel  sales. 

These  considerations  taken  together  lead  to  the  conclusion  that,  the  large 
changes  in  the  demand  for  steel,  which  were  associated  with  the  changes  in 
the  prices  of  steel  during  the  period  1936-1938,  were  the  result  of  (1)  changes 
in  business  conditions,  (2)  anticipation  of  future  price  changes,  and  (3) 
anticipation,  at  times,  of  future  delivery  delays,  rather  than  of  actual  changes 
in  the  price  of  steel. 

This  conclusion  is  verified  by  the  following  consideration  of  the  actual 
course  of  events  between  June,  1936,  and  October,  1939. 

IV.  Short  Run  Variations  in  the  Demand  for  Steel:  June  1936  to  October 

1939 

A.    THE   ECONOMIC    BACKGROUND,    1930   TO    1935 

To  analyze  the  behavior  of  the  demand  for  steel  in  the  period  June,  1936  to 
October,  1939,  an  understanding  of  the  economic  developments  in  the  depression 


13946       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

years  1930  to  1935  is  necessary.  These  prior  developments  can  be  most  fruitfully 
appraised  in  terms  of  their  later  effects  on  the  demand  for  steel  if  they  are  broken 
down  into  three  classes:  (1)  developments  affecting  the  potential  demand  for 
producei*'  durable  goods,  (2)  developments  affecting  the  potential  demand  for 
consumers'  durable  goods,  and  (3)  developments  in  Government  economic  policy. 
'(1)  Developments  Affecting  the  Potential  Demand  for  Producers'  Durable 
Goods 

(i)  The  population  of  the  United  States  at  the  end  of  the  year  1935 
was  almost  five  percent  greater  than  at  the  end  of  1929,  and  was  increas- 
ing at  the  rate  of  about  seven-tenths  percent  per  year. {2) 

(ii)  In  the  face  of  this  substantially  larger  potential  market  for  goods, 
the  productive  capacity  of  American  industry  had  actually  declined 
slightly.  The  accumulated  excess  of  consumption  of  business  plant  and 
equipment  over  production  of  these  goods  in  the  six  years  1930  to  1935 
amounted  to  more  than  three  and  a  half  billions  of  1929  dollars.  In 
the  six  years  1924  to  1929  there  had  been  a  net  excess  of  production 
over  consumption  of  these  goods  totaling  almost  twenty-one  billions  of 
1929  dollars.   (5) 

(iii)  Business  expenditures  (in  1929  dollars)  on  plant  and  equipment, 
which  at  the  bottom  of  the  depression  had  faUen  to  about  one-third  of 
their  1929  level,  had  in  1935  regained  only  about  one-third  of  ihe  depres- 
sion loss  and  then  stood  at  slightly  over  one-half  of  the  1929  level.' 
Practically  all  of  the  recovery  that  had  been  made  in  capital  expendi- 
tures, moreover,  had  been  gained  in  equipment  expenditures.  By  the 
end  of  1935  business  expenditures  on  equipment  had  regained  almost 
half  of  their  deprespion  loss,  and  were  approximately  two-thirds  of  the 
1929  figures.  (5)  Yet  business  expenditures  .on  plant,  "which  in  1933 
had  fallen  to  one-quarter  of  the  1929  amount,  had  in  1935  regained 
only  one-sixth  of  the  loss,  and  stood  at  less  than  forty  percent  of 
the  1929  level.     (5) 

It  is  thus  clear  that  up  to  the  beginning  of  1936  practically  no  recovery 
at  all  had  been  made  in  long-term  investment  commitments  in  the  busi- 
ness plant  of  the  country,  and  that  recovery  even  in  business  equipment 
expenditures  had  been  small.  Moreover,  what  recovery  there  had 
been  in  equipment  expenditures  consisted  largely  of  replacement  outlays 
made  on  a  short-term  basis  as  required  by  current  demands  on  pro- 
ductive capacity. 

(iv)  Behind  this  picture  of  small  recovery  in  capital  goods  production 
and  in  long  term  investments,  lies  another,  the  picture  of  a  similarly 
small  recovery  in  business  profits. 

In  1932  corporate  net  earnings  had  dropped  from  a  1929  peak  of  over 
$8  billion  to  a  net  deficit  of  over  $5  billion;  by  1935  they  had  recovered 
only  slightly  more  than  one-half  of  the  decline,  and  were  only  about 
one-fifth  of  the  1929  level.  (4)  Thus,  there  had  been  Uttle  incentive 
for  business  men  to  make  investment  commitments  in  the  years  1930 
,  to  1935.  (5)  But  more  important  in  interpreting  later  developments, 
the  fact  that  the  current  level  of  profits  at  the  end  of  1935  was  so  low, 
and  the  previous  six  years  on  balance  so  heavily  on  the  deficit  side,  {6) 
made  the  outlook  for  long  term  investment  in  heavy  capital  goods  an 
exceedingly  bleak  one. 

(v)  Contrasted  with  the  small  recovery  in  profits  and  business  capital 
outlays  was  a  somewhat  more  substantial  recovery  in  consumers'  outlay 
and  consumers'  income.  Consumers'  real  expenditures  in  1935  were 
only  about  thirteen  percent  below  the  1929  level,  and  had  regained  one- 
half  of  the  depression  loss.  (7)  Consumers'  real  income  in  1935  was 
similarly  only  about  thirteen  percent  below  its  1929  level.  (7)  By  the 
end  of  1935,  therefore,  1929  levels  of  activity  in  consumers'  goods  pro- 
duction were  not  far  distant. 

It  is  clear  that  the  recovery  which  had  taken  place  in  the  years  1933 
to  1935  was  largely  a  consumption  recovery,  with  capital  expenditures 
consisting  mostly  of  the  replacement  outlays  required  by  increasing 
production   of   consumers'    goods.     A   sustaining   base  of   recovery   in 
long  term  investment  commitments  was  absent. 
(2)   Developments  Affecting  the  Potential  Demand  for  Consumers'  Durable 
Goods. — Beside  the  five  percent  increase  in  population  which  had  occurred 
in  the  years  1930  to  1935,  three  important  developments  in  the  three  major 
categories  of  consumers'  durable  goods,  automobiles,  housing,  and  house- 
furnishings  had  taken  place: 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13947 

(i)  Automobiles  (8). — With  the  decline  in  income  after  1929,  consumers 
drastically  curtailed  their  purchases  of  new  automobiles.  In  the  low 
year,  1932,  passenger  car  sales  were  only  one-quarter  of  the  1929  level. 
With  consumer  income  increasing  the  years  1933  to  1935,  automobile 
sales  recovered  about  one-half  of  the  1929  to  1932  decline;  the  total  for 
1935  was  almost  two-thirds  of  that  for  1929.  (£») 

The  total  consumer  stock  of  passenger  cars,  which  had  increased 
seven  million  in  the  six  years  1924  to  1929,  had  grown  less  than  half  a 
million  in  the  six  depression  years  1930  to  1935.  (10)  Moreover,  the 
age  of  the  stock  had  increased  greatly. '  At  the  end  of  1935  almost 
half  of  the  cars  were  more  than  six  years  old,  whereas,  in  1929  only 
about  one-seventh  were,  more  than  six  years  old.  (10)  Thus,  at  the 
beginning  of  1936  there  loomed  a  very  large  potential  "modernization" 
demand  for  automobiles.  With  consumer  income  at  that  time  already 
not  far  from  pre-depression  levels,  only  small  increases  would  be  required 
to  bring  forth  that  demand. 

(ii)  Household  Furnishings. — Expenditures  (in  1929.  dollars)  for 
household  furnishings  fell  less  in  the  depression,  and  had  recovered  more 
than  for  automobiles.  At  the  bottom  in  1933  they  had  fallen  to  about 
55  percent  of  their  1929  level;  in  1934  and  1935  more  than  half  of  the 
loss  had  been  recovered.  (11)  In  the  case  of  household  furnishing  there 
existed  not  only  a  potential  replacement  demand,  but  also  a  large  poten- 
tial demand  for  "new  invention"  goods  which  had  only  begun  to  come 
on  the  market  before  the  depression — such  goods  as  electric  refrigerators 
and  other  new  electric  appliances. 

(iii)  Residential  Construction. — Developments  in  housing  were  in 
marked  contrast  to  those  of  other  consumers'  durable  goods.  Total 
expenditures  (in  1929  dollars)  on  residential  construction  at  their  Iqw 
point  in  1933  were  only  about  one-sixth  of  the  1929  figure,  and  approxi- 
mately one-tenth  of  the  predepression  peak  in  1925  when  the  total  was 
over  $5  billion.  '  Practically  no  recovery  was  made  in  1934,  and  in  1935 
the  total  was  only  about  40  per  cent  of  that  in  1929  and  only  one-quarter 
of  the  depression  drop  had  been  regained  by  that  time.  (12) 

The  result  of  this  drastic  decline  in  the  level  of  housing  expenditures 
was  the  accumulation  of  a  potentially  large  replacement  and  moderni- 
zation demand.  In  the  six  years  1930  to  1935  the  excess  of  consumption 
of  residential  housing  over  construction  had  accumulated  to  a  total  of 
eight  and  a  half  billions  of  1929  dollars,  about  seven  times  the  amount 
spent  in  1935,  and  almost  three  times  the  1929  total.  (12)  Add  to  this 
decline  of  the  stock  of  housing,  its  greatly  increased  average  age,  the 
five  percent  increase  of  population,  and  the  great  technical  developments 
in  housing  construction  and  it  is  clearly  apparent  that  at  the  beginning 
of  1936  there  was  an  extremely  large  potential  demand  for  housing. 

Although  relatively  unimporatnt  in  the  mid^t  of  the  depression,  the 

relation  between  rents  and  costs  became  increasingly  significant  in  the 

upswing,  particularly  in  early  1936.  (13)     From  1929  to  1933  the  decline 

in  construction  costs  in  most  localities  was  not  as  great  as  the  decline  in 

rentals.     However,  in  1934  and  1935  a  substantial  recovery  was  made 

in  rents  while  costs  rose  considerably  less.     Though  the  relation  of  rents 

to  costs  at  the  beginning  of  1936  was  more  favorable,  the  situation  was 

still  precarious;  a  rather  small  rise  in  costs  relative  to  rents  would  be 

sufficient  to  stop  recovery. 

(3)   Developments  in  the  Field  of  Government  Economic  Policy. — In   1933  the 

Federal  Government  inaugurated  an  unparalleled  program  of  particlipation 

in  the  economic  activity  of  the  country  in  the  hope  of  hastening  recovery 

The  most  important  of  the  developments  were: 

(i)  A  heavy  deficit  spending  program  in  which  the  net  contribution  of 
the  Federal  Government  to  disposable  cash  income  increased  from  an 
average  of  $160  million  a  month  in  the  last  ten  months  of  1933  to  $310 
million  a  month  in  1935.  (14) 

This  deficit  spending  was  a  very  important  factor  in  the  1933  to  1935 
recovery  of  consumers'  income  and  outlay,  but  uncertainty  as  to  the 
future  course  of  spending,  and  the  increase  of  the  Federal  debt,  (15)  con- 
tributed to  the  absence  of  recovery  in  new  lona;  term  investments. 

(ii)    Marked  changes  were  made  in    Government  monetary  policy. 
The  Thomas  inflation  amendments  to  the  Agricultural  Adjustment  Act 
in  1933,  the  devaluation  of  the  d6llar  and  the  Silver  Purchase  Act  of 
124491— 41— pt.  26 24 


13948       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

1934,  the  Banking  Act  of  1935,  along  with  a  rapid  and  uncontrolled'flow 
of  gold  into  the  United  States,  and  rise  of  the  Federal  debt  made  business 
men  extremely  apprehensive  of  rapid  price  inflation. 

(iii)  Government  support  of  increasing  wage  rates,  and  the  stimula- 
tion of  the  growth  of  labor  organizations  by  new  Federal  statutes 
brought  to  business  fears  of  rising  wage  costs  and  impending  production 
stoppages. 

(iv)  The  N.  R.  A.,  the  A.  A.  A.,  and  other  price-production  experi- 
ments made  business  men  highly  uncertain  as  to  the  future  course  of 
Government  industrial  policy. 
In  summary,  this  was  the  background  situation  at  the  beginning  of  1936: 

(1)  Consumers'  income  and  outlay  and  industrial  activity — 'except  in 
the  heavy  capital  goods  industries — were  already  approaching  pre- 
depression  levels. 

(2)  With  more  and  more  industries  nearing  capacity  operations,  the 
level  of  activity  at  which  business  expenditures  for  replacement  of 
equipment  could  no  longer  be  deferred  was  not  far  distant.  Greater 
activity  in  the  capital  equipment  industries  would  in  turn  increase  con- 
sumers' income  and  thus  the  demand  for  equipment. 

(3)  Similarly,  a  continued  rise  of  consumers'  income  was  almost  cer- 
tain shortly  to  bring  forth  the  "modernization"  demand  for  consumers' 
durable  goods  (except  possibly  housing)  whose  purchase  had  been  de- 
ferred in  the  previous  six  years  of  depression. 

(4)  The  belief  was  becoming  wide-spread  among  business  men  that 
the  policies  of  the  Federal  Government  would  lead  to  price  inflation. 

(5)  Investment — in  housing  and  business  plant — based  on  a  long 
term  outlook  had  mtide  little  recovery. 

The  situation  was  dominated  by  the  short  run  outlook,  and  was  for  that 
reason  vulnerable.  All  the  elements  of  a  short  run  boom  were  there,  but 
the  requirement  for  a  sustained  recovery — recovery  in  outlays  made  on  the 
basis  of  the  long  term  outlook — was  lacking.  Reasonable  certainty  as  to 
the  future  was  absent.  There  was  thiis  a  real  danger  that  a"  boom  might 
develop,  reach  runaway  proportions,  and  collapse  without  any  cushion  of 
long  term  industrial  activity  to  fall  back  upon. 

B.    THE   boom:    JULY    1936   TO    MARCH   lfl37 

Although  business  activity  had  declined  somewhat  in  the  winter  of  1935-1936, 
sentimeht  among  steel  consumers  by  mid-spring  was  predominantly  optimistic  in 
regard  to  immediate  prospects.  These  feelings  were  undoubtedly  strengthened 
by  the  rapid  and  unbroken  rise  which  advanced  stock  prices  more  than  two- 
thirds  above  their  March,  1935  level  (16)  and  the  fact  that  the  enactment  of  the 
Veterans'  Bonus  in  the  winter  promised  a  high  level  of  activity  in  the  last  six 
months  of  1936.  By  May,  most  of  the  business  activity  indexes  were  moving 
upward,  some  experiencing  rather  substantial  contra-seasonal  rises.  But  the 
situation  as  yet  had  little  of  the  characteristics  of  a  boom,  although  there  was 
beginning  to  be  considerable  discussion  of  the  possibility  of  inflation. 

(1)  Initiation  of  the  Boom — July  to  December  19S6. — A  combination  of  events 
beginning  in  the  three  months  May,  June,  and  July,  1936,  however,  started  an 
upward  movement  of  prices  and  industrial  production  which  reached  the  status 
of  a  boom  by  the  end  of  the  year: 

(i)  Payment  of  the  Veterans'  Bonus  in  June  brought  about  a  big  increase 
in  consumers'  income.  {17)  The  result  of  the  payment  was  to  be  felt  in  the 
next  six  or  eight  months  through  its  effect  on  sales  of  consumers'  goods. 

(ii)  The  agrioultural  drought  early  in  the  1936  crop  season,  and  world- 
wide re-armament  accelerated  by  the  Spanish  Civil  War  led  to  a  rapid  rise 
in  the  prices  of  basic  agricultural  products  and  industrial  raw  materials.  (,18) 
(iii)   Of  great  importance  in  strengthening  the  feeling  of  price  inflation  in 
the  summer  of  1936  was  the  prospect  of  higher  wage  rates  arising  out  of 
threats  to  organize  such  basic  industries  as  steel  and  automobiles. 
The  addition  of  these  developments  to  a  situation  already  containing  the  basic 
elements  of  a  boom  was  all  that  was  necessary  to  make  the  boom — and  price 
inflation — a  reality. 

The  progress  of  the  boom  as  it  affected  the  steel  industry  in  the  last  six  months 
of  i936  is  indicated  in  Table  1.  Instead  of  the  usual  summer  decline  in  orders, 
f'aipments,  and  production,  actual  increases  occurred,  so  that  the  third  quarter 
was  somewhat  better  than  the  second.  By  the  beginning  of  the  last  quarter 
activity  had  definitely  taken  on  boom  proportions. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13949 


Table  1.- 


-Composite  Steel  Price,  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries  Bookings 
and  Shipments,  and  Total  Ingot  Production 


Iron  Age 

Composite 

Price  of   ' 

Finished 

Steel  (cents 

per  pound)' 

(1) 

U.  8.  Steel 
Corp. 

Domestic 
Bookings  of 
Rolled  and 

Finished 
Steel  (OOO's 
of  gross  -ind 

net  tons)» 

(2) 

U.  S.  Steel 

Corp. 
Domestic 
Shipments  of 
Rolled  and 
Finished 
Steel  (OOO's 
of  gross  and 
net  tons)' 

(3) 

Steel  Ingot  Production  In  the 
United  States 

Date 

Total 

(OOO's  of 

gross 

tons)' 

(4) 

Percent 

of 
capacity 

(6) 

Federal  Re- 
serve 
Board 
Index 

Adjusted  for 

Variation 
(1923-25 
=  100)  * 

(6) 

1929* 

2.2m 
2.048 
1.957 
1.901 
1.8'9 
2.033 
2.058 

2.062 
Z040 
2.021 
2.028 

2  028 
2.033 
2  091 
2.081 
2.096 
2.116 
2.116 
2.199 

1,264.9 
923.9 
554.9 
274.1 
433.8 
520.1 
619.0 

771.0 
604.9 
926.3 
877.1 
818.4 
1,055.8 

1. 092. 4 
R3&9 
953.8 

1. 144. 5 
909.0 

2,033.3 

1,168.9 
900.1 
596.9 
311.8 
460.6 
449.3 
672.7 

688.8 
619.2 
736.0 
931.9 
883.6 
876.7 
886.3 
874.4 
898.1 
952.7 
863.1 
985.9 

4,571 
3,300 
2,119 
1,122 
1,908 
2.162 
2,828 

3.086 
3,002 
3,384 
3,991 
4,097 
4.035 
3,976 
4,247 
4,214 
4,601 
4,389 
4,491 

89.05 
63.09 
3&13 
19.76 
33.53 
37.:38 
48.64 

52.39 
54.63 
67. 4C 
69.99 
69.68 
70.75 
67.6] 
72.11 
74.06 
78.15 
76.94 
76.42 

131 

1930* 

96 

1931* 

01 

1832* 

32 

1933* 

1034* 

M 

83 

1935* 

81 

1936 
Jan  —          .  — 

88 

Frt>  \ 

86 

Mm 

86 

Apr 

102 

May"        - - 

107 

Juno 

116 

July    - 

121 

Aug          -  .  . 

123 

s^:::, :..::; 

121 

S^o^v ----- 

ISO 
1^ 

Dec 

147 

Monthly  Average 

2.077 

999.6 

•848.6 

3.959 

68.36 

113 

1937 
Jnn 

2.249 
2.249 
2.459 
2.512 
2.512 
2.612 
2.612 
2.512 
2.512 
2.512 
2.512 
2.612 

1,302.8 
1, 270. 1 
1,839.2 
1, 167. 0 

866.' 9 
840.6 
793.7 
693.0 
511.0 
471.  J 
477.9 

1, 143. 2 

1,040.8 

1,332.9 

1,224.8 

1,211.8 

1,174.0 

1,060.6 

971.7 

946.9 

665.3 

470.1 

406.6 

4.786 
4,498 
6,303 
5,156 
5,237 
4,254 
4.631 
4,968 
4,362 
3.449 
2,189 

81.32 
84.27 
89.94 
90.26 
88.79 
74.48 
78.48 
83.83 
76.30 
58.31 
38.23 
25.37 

142 

Feb      

131 

Mar    

128 

Apr 

132 

Mii  :: ::: .: 

136 

Tnnf> 

121 

July  -  —  - 

141 

Aug        

144 

Sept 

125 

Oct : . 

101 

Nov        .      ... 

68 

Deo 

49 

Monthly  Average 

2.464 

922.7 

965.7 

4.193 

72.38 

118 

1938 
Jan L . 

Z512 
2.512 
2.512 
2.612 
2.506 
2.459 
2.300 
2.300 
2.293 
2.265 
2.286 
■2.286 

426.8 
376.9 
503.8 
541.8 
3.38.3 
428.6 
485.0 
518.1 
663.5 
729.1 
778.0 
665.0 

484.1 
380.4 
476.4 
450.6 
399.6 
443.6 
410.6 
626.3 
525.7 
636.1 
628.7 
670.3 

1,733 
1,704 
2,012 
1,925 
1,807 
1,638 
1,982 
2,647 
2,658 
3,118 
3,572 
3,143 

29.15 
31.74 
33.85 
33.44 
30.39 
28.40 
33.42 
42. 85 
46.28 
52.45 
62.05 
53.00 

52 

Feb - 

61 

Mar. 

49 

Apr   .- - 

60 

mi: :::: 

48 

June 

47 

July    

64 

72 

setrt"::.::::::::::::"" 

77 

Oct 

92 

Nov    

112 

Dec 

104 

Monthly  Average 

2.394 

636.2 

602.1 

2.320 

39.79. 

68 

•  Average  of  monthly  figures. 

'  See:  The  Iron  Age,  January  6,  1939,  p.  199. 

'  Source:  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation. 

'  Sec:  The  Irov  Age,  January  6,  1939,  p.  191. 

*  See:  Federal  Reserve  BvMetin,  June  1937,  July  1937,  p.  675,  July  1938,  p. 
p.  916. 


3,  July  1939,  p.  694.  October,  1939, 


13950  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  L — Composite  Steel  Price,   U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries  Bookings 
and  Shipments,  and  Total  Ingot  Production — Continued 


Jan.. 
Feb. 

Mar. 
Apr. 
May, 
June. 
July. 
Aug. 
Sept. 


Iron  Age 

Composite 

Price  of 

Finished 

Steel  (cents 

per  pound) 


2.286 
2.286 
2.286 
2.286 
2.236 
2.236 
2.236 
2.236 
2.236 


U.  S.  Steel 
Corp. 

Domestic 
Bookings  of 
Rolled  and 

Finished 
Steel  (OOO's 
of  gross  and 

net  tons) 


(2) 


622.9 
662.4 
603.6 
623.9 
670.9 
655.3 
719.3 


U.  S.  Steel 

Corp. 
Domestic 
Shipments  of 
Rolled  and 
Finished 
Steel  (OOO's 
of  gross  and 
net  tons) 


734.6 
602.7 
678.1 
715.0 
639.0 
662.6 
618.0 


Steel  Ingot  Production  in  the 
United  States 


Total 
(OOO's  of 


3,174 
2,989 
3,405 
2,974 


Percent 

of 
capacity 


52.69 
64.10 
66.14 
50.99 
48.24 
53.44 
52.40 
62.22 


Federal  Re- 
serve 
Board 
Index 

Adjusted  for 


Variation 
(1923-25 
=  100) 


»  The  1939  figures  for  The  Iron  Age  Composite  Price  of  Finished  Steel  are  for  the  middle  week  af  the  respec- 
tive months,  and  are  from  current  issues  of  The  Iron  Aqe.  The  1939  figures  for  columns  (4)  and  (5)  are  from 
current  issues  of  The  Iron  Age.  The  1939  figures  for  total  steel  ingot  produrtion  (column  4)  do  not  include 
steel  for  castings.  The  1939  bookings  figures  are  not  strictly  comparable  to  those  of  previous  years  since 
they  do  not  include  "requirement  contrncts"-  that  is,  "price  protection"  contracts  without  actual 
specifications. 

The  developments  of  the  last  six  months  of  1936  can  best  be  analyzed  in 
terms  of  their  effects  on  the  demand  for  steel  if  they  are  studied  in  three  groups: 
(a)  Developments  affecting  the  demand  for  steel  by  the  consumers'  goods  indus- 
tries; (b)  Developments  affecting  the  demand  for  steel  by  the  producers'  goods 
industries;  and  (c)  Behavior  of  the  price  of  steel. 

(a)   Developments  Affecting  the  Demand  for  Steel  by  the  Consumers'  Goods 
Industries 

(1)  Automobiles. — By  the  time  production  of  the  new  1937  models  was 
in  full  swing  in  October,  1936,  automobile  makers  were  already  predict- 
ing a  5,000,000  car  year,  i.e.,  one  about  as  large  as  that  in  1929.  (19) 
Automobile  producers  justified  their  anticipation  on  the  basis  of  (1)  the 
unusually  high  level  of  sales  in  the  spring,  (.20)  (2)  the  generally  rapid- 
rise  of  consumers'  income  and  industrial  activity  and  the  widespread 
optimisrti  that  business  activity  was  going  to  continue  upward,  (3)  the 
boost  to  sales  expected  as  a  result  of  the  Veterans'  Bonus,  and  (4)  a 
recognition  that  consumers  had  a  large  depression  "backlog  of  deferred 
purchases"  to  make  up. 

Nor  were  these  feelings  unjustified  by  the  events  of  the  last  quarter 
of  1936.  In  October,  November,  and  Decemoer,  orders  for  the  1937 
models  poured  in  to  producers  at  a  1929  pace. (21)  Seasonally  adjusted 
retail  sales  of  automobiles  in  November  and  December  were  up  to  the 
1929  peak  level  and  about  forty  percent  greater  than  the  corresponding 
months  in  1935.(^0) 

By  the  end  of  December,  automobile  producers  had  already  placed 
~  orders  for  considerably  more  than  half  of  the  steel  requirements  on 
their  expected  production  of  1937  models.  (.?,?)  Inasmuch  as  the  auto- 
motive industry  was  the  biggest  steel  consumer,  these  orders  were  un- 
doubtedly a  major  factor  accounting  for  the  high  level  of  steel  bookings 
jn  the  last  four  months  of  1936. 

(2)  Household  Goods. — The  situation  in  the  household  goods  industry 
was  not  substantially  different  from  that  in  automobiles.  Though  few 
monthly  figures  on  orders,  sales,  or  production  of  household  goods  are 
available,  cjiiarterly  data  for  sales  of  electric  stoves  and  electric  house- 
hold refrigerators,  and  shipments  of  vacuum  cleaners  indicate  that 
sales  of  household  goods  in  the  las.t  quarter  of  1936  must  have  been 
25%  to  50%  greater  than  in  the  corresponding  quarter  of  1935.(23) 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13951 

Although  the  household  goods  industry  is  not  one  of  the  major  con- 
sumers of  steel,  some  rather  substantial  tonnages  were  undoubtedly 
placed  in  the  last  half  of  1936,  especially  for  lighter  types  of  steel. 

(3)  Residential  Construction. — Activity  in  residential  construction'was 
in  marked  contrast  to  that  in  automobiles  and  household  goods.  In 
March,  1936,  the  value  of  residential  construction  contract  awards 
begJan  a  rapid  upward  climb.  By  mid-summer  it  appeared  that  the 
long-delayed  recovery  in  housing  was  at  last  under  way;  August  con- 
tract awards  (adjusted  for  seasonal  variation)  were  over  80  per  cent 
greater  than  for  February.  (:?-^) 

However,  the  recovery  was  short-lived.  Contract  awards  (seasonally 
adjusted)  reached  a  peak  as  early  as  September,  and  were  about  seven 
per  cent  lower  in  the  last  quarter  than  in  the  third.  An  important 
factor  in  cutting  short  recovery  was  the  rise  in  building  costs  that  took 
place  in  the  last  half  of  1936.  (i5)  Though  residential  construction 
undoubtedly  contributed  to  the  high  level  of  steel  activity  in  the  last 
half  of  1936,  it  was  apparent  before  the  end  of  the  year  that — barring 
an  unusual  rise  in  rents,  or  a  miracle — no  further  stimulus  could  be 
.  expected  from  that  quarter.  Already  an  important  deflationary  element 
had  entered  the  picture. 

(b)  Developments  Affecting  the  Demand  for  Steel  by  the  Producers'  Goods 
Industries 

(1)  Railroads. — In  April,  1936,  freight  car  loadings  began  an  upward 
rise,  which  increased  in  rapidity  in  the  following  summer  and  autumn. 
By  December,  1936,  they  had  advanced  to  a  level  about  twenty-five 
per  cent  above  the  March  figure  and  that  for  the  previous  December. 
Although  the  level  of  freight  car  loadings  in  the  last  half  of  1936  was 
about  twenty-five  per  cent  under  the  1929  amount,  the  railroads'  stock 
of  serviceable  freight  cars  had  been  so  depleted  (by  failure  to  replace) 
in  the  depression  years  that  the  freight  car  surplus  in  the  last  half  of 
1936  M^as  actually  more  than  forty  percent  under  the  1929  average 
surplus.  (.^5) 

Revenue  passenger-miles  in  the  last  half  of  1936  were  about  twenty-five 
per  cent  above  the  first  half  of  1936.(^5) 

As  a  result  of  increased  freight  and  passenger  traffic,  net  railway 
operating  income  advanced  rapidly.  The  average  for  the  last  quarter 
of  1936  was  over  30  per  cent  greater  than  for  the  fourth  quarter  of 

1935.  The  railroads'  net  income  for  the  same  periods  rose  from  $63 
million  to  $126  million.  (.^5) 

With  traffic  nearing  capacity  levels,  and  with  a  greatly  improved  profit 
outlook  and  current  income  situation,  the  railroads  came  into  the  market 
with  a  tremendous  upward  spurt  of  orders  in  November  and  December, 
1936.(^7)  New  orders  of  freight  cars  in  December  were  greater  than 
the  total  for  the  year  1935.  The  number  of  new  locomotives  ordered 
in  November  and  December  was  greater  than  the  combined  total  for 
the  three  years  1932  to  1934.  Orders  for  passenger  cars  and  steel  rails 
similarly  showed  great  increases.  Undoubtedly  the  greatly  increased 
demand  of  the  railroads  for  rails  and  rolling  stock  was  an  important 
factor  in  the  great  rise  in  bookings  of  heavy  steel  in  the  last'quarter  of 

1936,  and  especially  in  December. 

(2)  Machinery  and  Equipment. — What  was  happening  in  the  railroad 
industry  was  happening  more  or  less  •  similarly  in  industry  jn  general. 
In  April,  1936,  industrial  production  began  to  move  rapidly  upward; 
by  December  it  had  advanced  more  than  twenty-five  per  cent  over 
March  (on  a  seasonally  adjusted  basis),  and  had  actuaUy  reached  the 
average  level  for  1929.(5)  In  view  of  the  decline  of  the  stock  of  ma- 
chinery and  equipment  that  had  taken  place  since  1929,  wide  areas  of 
industry  were  undoubtedly  operating  at  or  near  capacity  in  the  last  half 
of  1936.  Thus,  if  demands  on  productive  capacity  were  to  be  met,  fur- 
ther postponement  of  outlays  for  replacement  of  industrial  equipment 
was  no  longer  possible. 

An  added  incentive  to  make  equipment  outlays  came  from  the  fact 
that  the  profit  outlook  was  substantially  improved.  Profits  of  indus- 
trial corporations  for  the  fourth  quarter  of  1936  were  more  than  forty 
percent  above  the  corresponding  period  of  1935,  although  still  not  much 
more  than  half  the  1929  level.  (^5) 


13952  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

By  mid-summer  new  orders  of  industrial  equipment  were  increasing 
rapidly,  and  by  autumn  activity  in  the  machinery  and  equipment  indus- 
try was  definitely  in  the  boom  stage.  The  year  1936  ended  with  a 
tremendous  spurt  of  new  orders  in  December.  {27) 

Part  of  the  increase  of  new  orders  was  caused  by  rising  equipment 
prices  in  the  last  half  of  1936,  and  the  expectation  that  prices  were  going 
to  rise  still  further.  (;gS)  A  substantial  volume  of  orders  for  equipment 
which  was  not  required  by  current  demands  on  capacity  and  which 
otherwise  might  not  have  been  purchased  was  placed  as  protection  against 
expected  price  advances.  This  was  undoubtedly  true  in  December  when 
widespread  expectations  of  price  advances  early  in  the  first  quarter  of  1937 
caused  many  buyers  to  protect  themselves  by  ordering  in  advance.  (;85) 

(3)  Business  Construction. — Activity  in  the  business  construction  in- 
dustry began  to  rise  in  the  spring  of  1936,  and  continued  to  advance 
throughout  the  remainder  of  the  year,  but  at  a  slower  pace  in  the  last 
quarter.  (;85)  Although  the  total  value  of  construction  contracts 
awarded  for  commercial  and  factory  buildings  and  public  utilities  in  the 
last  half  of  1936  rras  more  than  sixty  percent  greater  than  for  the  same 
period  in  1935,  it  was  only  slightly  more  than  one-sixth  of  the  total  for 
the  full  year  1929;  recovery  was  undoubtedly  still  being  impeded  by 
the  low  level  of  profits.  However,  the  increase  in  1936  contributed 
importantly  to  the  advance  of  activity  in  heavy  steel  production. 

(4)  Public  Construction. — Developments  in  public  construction  were 
markedly  diflFerent  from  those  in  pri'vate  building.  The  value  of  con- 
struction contracts  awarded  for  public  buildings  and  public  works  and 
the  value  of  highway  and  grade  crossing  projects  approved  for  con- 
struction, which  had  risen  very  rapidly  in  the  years  1934  and  1935, 
continued  to  increase  throughout  most  of  the  first  half  of  193Q.(29) 
The  peak,  however,  was  reached  early  in  the  summer,  and  the  last  half 
of  the  year  was  largely  one  of  decline.    The  reasons  for  the  decline  were: 

(i)  With  private  industrial  activity  increasing,  there  was  less  pressure 
to  provide  employment  on  public  projects;  and 

(ii)  Fears  that  continued  public  spending  would  lead  to  runaway 
price  inflations  and  demands  for  a  baJanced  Federal  budget  prom{)ted 
a  reduction  of  Federal  construction  outlays. 

Though  public  construction  expenditures  even  in  the  last  half  of  1936 
were  at  a  higher  level  than  for  1935,  the  outlook  for  1937  was  one  of  a 
continuing  reduction.  Thus  another  important  deflationary  element 
was  added  to  the  prospects  for  1937. 

(c)  The  Behavior  of  the  Price  of  Steel. — From  the  discussion  of  the  previous 
pages,  it  is  apparent  that  the  great  upward  shift  of  the  demand  for  producers' 
and  consumers'  goods  in  the  last  half  pf  1936  undoubtedly  would  have  caused 
a  large  increase  in  the  demand  for  steel  irrespective  of  what  had  happened 
to  its  price.  As  we  shall  see,  however,  the  behavior  of  the  price  of  steel 
actually  increased  this  demand. 

During  the  first  half  of  1936  steel  prices  were  for  the  most  part  unchanged. 
In  the  last  part  of  May,  however,  leading  steel  producers  announced  small 
price  advances  on  many  steel  products  effective  beginning  July  1,  for  third 
quarter  shipments.  The  increases  raised  the  average  level  of  steel  prices 
about  three  or  four  per  cent.  (50)  The  effect  of  the  price  advances  was  to 
strengthen  expectations  of  further  price  increases.  (S/)  There  followed  a  sub- 
stantial amount  of  orders  in  June  as  protection  against  price  increases.  (S^) 
There  is  no  evidence  that  the  price  increases  had  any  important  effect  on 
steel  purchases  in  the  third  quarter;  July  bookings  were  greater  than  the 
total  for  June,  and  the  total  for  the  third  quarter  greater  than  that  fo^^the 
second.  (33) 

Prices  for  a  few  steel  items  were  raised  in  September  and  October,  1936,  but 
the  effects  of  the  advances  were  slight,  except  to  further  the  now  widespread 
anticipations  of  substantial  increases  over  a  wide  range  of  steel  products.  (54) 
These  expectations  were  bolstered  by  (1)  rapidly  rising  prices  elsewhere  in 
the  economy,  (55)  (2)  the  great  increase  in  steel  activity,  (3)  the  "rising  cost 
of  steel  scrap,  (5(5)  and  (4)  expectations  of  an  early  rise  in  wage  rates  in  the 
steel  industry.  (57) 

On  November  16,  1936,  a  wage  rate  increase  of  approximately  ten  per  cent 
was  granted  to  steel  workers  by  the  majority  of  steel  producers.  (57)  The 
effect  of  this  advance  was  materially  to  incroi^f*  ^^<^  T>at  of  steel  production 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13953 

Other  increased  costs  had  become  effective  in  1936,  including  the  Social 
Security  Tax,  and,  in  the  case  of  the  manufacturing  subsidiaries  of  United 
States  Steel  Corporation,  vacations  with  pay  to  certain  employees.  Soon 
after  the  wage  advance  of  November,  1936,  price  announcements  for  ship- 
ments during  the  first  quarter  of  1937  were  made  by  the  principal  steel 
producers.  The  announced  price  increases  covered  practically  the  whole 
range  of  important  steel  products  and  raised  the  average  level  of  steel  prices 
about  six  per  cent.  (38)  The  immediate  effect  of  the  price  advance  was  the 
placing  in  December  of  a  very  large  amount  of  forward  orders  as  protection 
against  the  announced  January  price  advances.  (35)  December  bookings  of 
the  subsidiaries  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  were  more  than  double 
those  in  November,  more  than  twenty-five  percent  greater  than  the  peak 
month  in  1929,  and  were  the  largest  monthly  post-war  bookings  in  the 
history  of  the  Corporation.  (40) 

Although  a  great  increase  in  bookings  might  have  been  expected  in  De- 
cember because  of  a  simultaneous  large  upward  shift  in  the  demand  for 
products  made  from  steel,  (4^)  the  magnitude  of  the  increase  indicates  clearly 
the  importance  of  speculative  forward  buying  in  that  month. 

An  additional  element  that  entered  the  picture  in  December,  1936,  and 
stimulated  buying,  was  that  deliveries — especially  of  steel  sheets — were 
being  delayed  by  pressure  on  capacity.  By  mid-December  deliveries  of  steel 
sheets,  for  example,  could  ^not  be  promised  within  less  than  three  or  four 
months.  (4^)  With  producers  of  products  made  from  steel  expecting  large 
steel  production  requirements  in  the  first  six  or  eight  months  of  1937,  some 
forward  tonnages  were  placed  in  December  as  protection  against  future 
delivery  delay. 

(2)  The  Critical  Period:  January  to  March  1937. — Domestic  bookings  of  steel 
in  January  and  February  1937  dropped  approximately  35  per  cent  from  the  De- 
cember level  although  they  were  still  about  30  per  cent  above  the  level  of  the 
previous  October  and  November.  (35)  The  most  important  reasons  for  the 
decline  were: 

(i)  Steel  consumers  had  undoubtedly  covered  a  large  part  of  their  first 
and  second  quarter  requireinents  in  1937  -by  orders  in  the  last  quarter  of 
1936,  and  especially  in  December.  (43) 

(ii)  Further  steel  price  advances,  although  anticipated  as  the  outcome  of 
rising  costs  in  the  steel  industry,  were  not  expected  much  before  the  begin- 
ning of  the  second  quarter  of  1937.(44)  Thus  in  January  and  February 
there  was  little  price  incentive  for  protective  forward  buying.  This  factor 
alone  is  sufficient  to  account  for  a  large  part  of  the  drop  from  December, 
1936,  when  advance  buying  had  been  very  large. 

(iii)  New  orders  of  products  made  from  steel  similarly  had  declined  from 
a  high  forward  buying  level  in  December,  1936.(45) 

(iv)  Widespread  strikes  prevented  substantial  specifications  of  steel  from 
the  automobile  industry. 

Although  bookings  had  declined,  the  large  backlog  of  orders,  placed  in  the  last 
quarter  of  1936,  raised  production  and  shipments  of  steel  in  January  and  Febru- 
ary, 1937,  above  the  corresponding  December  figures.  (33) 

In  March,  however,  there  was  another  upswing  in  orders  of  steel.  Bookings 
were  almost  fifty  per  cent  greater  than  for  February,  but  were  about  10  per  cent 
under  the  peak  figure  for  December,  1936.(33)  Several  factors  were  responsible 
for  the  increase  in  orders  in  March: 

(i)  On  March  2,  1937,  Carnegie-Illinois  Steel  Corporation  signed  a  labor 
contract  with  the  Steel  Workers  Organizing  Committee  which  was  followed 
by  formal  contracts  signed  a  few  days  subsequently  by  this  and  other  manu- 
facturing subsidiaries  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation.  Under  these  con- 
tracts the  basic  common  labor  rate  was  increased  about  twenty  percent 
and  there  was  established  an  eight-hour  working  day  and  a  forty-hour  work- 
ing week,  with  time  and  a  half  compensation  for  all  overtime  in  excess  of 
eight  hours  in  any  day,  or  in  excess  of  forty  hours  in  any  week,  such  changes 
becoming  effective  March  16,  1937.  Other  steel  producers  granted  similar 
wage  advances.  The  signing  of  this  first  labor  contract  was  immediately 
followed  by  the  announcement  by  various  subsidiaries  of  United  States 
Steel  Corporation  in  the  first  week  of  March,  1937  of  price  increases  on  most 
steel  products.  Similar  price  increases  were  announced  by  other  steel  pro- 
ducers.    These  price  increases  on  the  average  raised  second  quarter  prices 


13954  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

about  ten  percent  above  the  level  for  the  first  quarter.  (4^)  The  announce- 
ment of  Carnegie-Illinois  Steel  Corporation  stated  that  the  price  increases 
were  necessary  to  cover  the  increased  cost  of  production  due  to  labor  ad- 
vances. A  considerable  part  of  the  new  orders  in  March  consisted  of  forward 
purchases  placed  as  protection  against  these  second  quarter  price  advances. 

(ii)  At  the  same  time  the  demand  for  products  made  from  steel  rose  greatly 
in  March.  Sales  of  automobiles  and  house-furnishings  were  much  larger 
than  in  January  and  February. (47)  Rising  industrial  production  and  an- 
ticipations of  price  increases  also  occasioned  a  large  upward  spurt  of  new 
orders  for  machinery  and  equipment.  (45) 

(iii)  Some  large  tonnages  were  also  placed  as  protection  against  future 
delivery  delay.  In  March,  delivery  for  some  of  the  light  hnished  steels 
could  not  be  promised  within  less  than  approximately  six  months.  (45) 
Threatened  production-stoppages  due  to  possible  labor  difficulties  bolstered 
these  fears  of  delivery  delay. 

In  the  meantime,  however,  several  critical  developments  pointing  to  an  almost 
certain  early  collapse  of  steel  buying  were  materializing: 

(i)  After  a  rapid  rise  in  1936,  a  decline  of  over  1.5  percent  in  real  income 
(adjusted  for  seasonal  variation)  occurred  in  January,  1937,  and  by  March 
it  was  .beginning  to  be  apparent  that  consumers'  real  income  was  in  the 
leveling  off  stage.  (50) 

In  addition,  the  Federal  Government  was  reducing  its  expenditures  while 
at  the  same  time  considerably  increasing  its  tax  revenues;  (14)  the  increase 
was  due  largely  to  heavy  Social  Security  Tax  collections  beginnuig  in  January 
1937.  As  a  result,  the  net  contribution  of  the  Federal  Government  to 
consumers'  disposable  cash  income  dropped  from  an  average  of  $370  million 
per  month  in  the  last  six  months  of  1936  t6  about  $110  million  per  month  in 
the  first  four  months  of  1937.  Such  a  reduction  was  large  enough  to  have 
significant  deflationary  effects.  Since  Government  policy  in  the  winter 
and  spring  of  1937  was  definitely  toward  a  reduction  of  expenditures,  the 
outlook  was  for  even  further  declinp. 

The  great  upswing  in  sales  of  consumers'  goods  in  1936  and  the  first 
quarter  of  1937  had  been  abnormal.  A  substantial  part  of  the  sales  un- 
doubtedly consisted  of  "modernization  replacement"  purchases  which 
had  been  deferred  in  the  previous  depression  years,  and  which  were  made 
under  the  stimulus  of  the  Veterans'  Bonus  and  rapidly  rising  income.  With 
a  considerable  part  of  the  deferred  backlog  of  purchases  already  made  up,  by 
the  spring  of  1937,  sales  of  durable  goods  could  not  be  expected  to  continue 
at  the  high  pace  of  the  previous  nine  months  unless  consumers'  income  should 
continue  to  increase  very  rapidly.  If  consumers'  income  should  decline,  the 
level  of  sales  was  almost  certain  to  drop. 

Figures  for  automobile  sales  tend  to  support  the  above  conclusion.  The 
peak  of  sales  (on  a  seasonally  adjusted  basis)  was  reached  as  early  as  Decem- 
ber 1936.  (20)  March,  1937,  was  about  5  per  cent  below  December,  1936, 
and  June,  1937,  about  20  percent  below  March. 

Taking  all  these  facts  into  consideration,  the  outlook  at  the  beginning  of 
the  spring  of  1937  was  very  definitely  toward  a  leveling  off  of,  or  a  decline  in, 
consumers'  expenditures.  The  immediate  prospects  for  the  consumers' 
durable  goods  industries  were  thus  definitely  not  bright. 

(ii).  A  somewhat  similar  situation  existed  for  the  durable  producers'  goods 
industries.  Business  expenditures  for  equipment  in  the  twelve  months, 
March,  1936  to  March,  1937,  were  about  50  per  cent  greater  than  the  corre- 
sponding outlays  for  1935,  and  were  at  a  level  about  equal  to  that  in  1929.  (51) 
By  the  spring  of  1937  it  was  probably  true  that  a  major  part  of  the  backlog 
of  replacement  outlays  deferred  in  the  depression  years  had  been  made  up. 
Thus,  unless  industrial  production  continued  to  increase  at  a  rapid  rate  so 
that  substantial  outlays  for  expansion  were  required,  expenditures  on  machin- 
ery and  equipment  were  almost  certain  to  decline. 

But  by  the  end  of  March,  1937,  it  was  becoming  clear  that  industrial 
production  was  not  going  to  continue  its  rapid  advance.  The  Federal 
Reserve  Board  index  of  industrial  production  (adjusted  for  seasonal  varia- 
tion) reached  a  peak  in  December  1936  slightly  above  the  1929  average, 
declined  almost  six  per  cent  in  January,  1937,  rose  slightly  in  February  and 
March  and  then  levelled  off  and  began  to  decline  in  the  second  quarter.  (6) 
Manufacture  of  non-durable  goods  (seasonallv  adjusted)  was  definitely  on 
the  deelir  e  bv  the  end  of  March,  1937.  (6) 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13955 

The  situation  was  aggravated  by  the  fact  that  piofits,  after  rising  rapidly 
in  1936,  also  began  to  level  off  early  in  1937.  Seasonally  adjusted  profits  for 
the  first  quarter  were  about  one-sixth  under  the  peak  in  the  fourth  quarter 
of  1936.  {26) 

Additional  disturbing  elements  in  the  first  quarter  of  1937  were  the  strikes 
in  the  automobile,  glass,  rubber,  machinery,  and  maritime  industries,  and 
organizational  activities  in  the  iron  and  steel  industry.  The  number  of 
strikes  in  progress  in  the  United  States  trebled  between  December  and 
March,  (52)  and  there  was  little  indication  that  production  stoppages  were 
going  to  decline. 

(iii)  The  outlook  for  the  railroads  was  also  becoming  much  less  optimistic. 
Merchandise  freight  car  loadings  (seasonally  adjusted)  began  to  decline  as 
early  as  December,  1936,  and  miscellaneous  loadings  followed  in  February, 
1937.  (53)  With  traffic  dropping  off,  though  slowly  at  first,  and  with  heavy 
replacement  expenditures  already  made  in  the  last  quarter  of  1936  and  the 
first  quarter  of  1937,  the  pressure  to  provide  further  replacement  was  relaxed. 
Railroad  baying  collapsed  in  the  second  quarter. 

The  collapse  was  hastened  by  the  decline  of  the  railroads'  income.  Net 
income  for  each  of  the  first  and  second  quarters  was  far  under  the  figure  for 
the  last  quarter  of  1936.    (25) 

(iv)  By  April,  1937,  there  was  a  growing  feeling  that  prices,  which  had 
risen  rapidly  in  the  previous  nine  months,  were  very  shortly  going  to  sta- 
bilize. (54)  Factors  important  in  dampening  speculative  anticipation  of  fur- 
ther price  inflation  were: 

(a)  The  excess  of  Government  expenditures  over  receipts  was  being 
rapidly     reduced. 

(b)  On  Deceml)er  21,  1936,  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury  announced 
the  gold  sterilization  policy,  whereby  gold  inflows  were  to  be  prevented 
from  contributing  to  inflation. 

Cc)  This  was  followed  on  January  30,  1937,  by  the  Federal  Reserve 
Board  announcement  of  a  33H  per  cent  increase  in  enember  banks' 
reserve    requirements. 

(d)  In  January  and  February  substantial  increases  in  the  yields  of 
government  bonds  occurred,  and  in  March  stock  prices  began  to  fall.    (55) 

(e)  Rumors  of  an  upward  revaluation  of  the  dollar  in  terms  of  gold 
had  become  so  strong  in  the  first  quarter  of  1937,  that  President  Roose- 
velt was  prompted  to  make  a  statement  on  April  9th  that  no  change  in 
the  United  States'  gold  policy  was  contemplated. 

(f)  In  March,  prices  of  basic  raw  materials  began  to  level  off.   (^.S) 

With  expectations  of  further  price  advances  disappearing,  a  most  important 
stimulus  to  forward  buying  was  being  removed.  Unquestionably  many 
orders  both  of  steel  and  of  products  made  from  steel  placed  in  the  nine 
months  JuW,  1936  to  March,  1937  had  been  of  the  speculative  price  pro- 
tection  variety.  - 

(v)  The  mere  fact  that  advance  buying  both  of  steel  and  df  products  made' 
from  steel  had  been  so  heavy  in  the  fourth  quarter  of  1936  and  the  first 
quarter  of  1937  pointed  to  a  much  lower  level  of  orders  throughout  the  two  or 
three  following  quarters.  By  the  end  of  March  buyers  of  steel  had  covered 
a  large  part  of  their  steel  requirements  for  the  next  six  or  eight  months. 
Total  domestic  bookings  of  subsidiaries  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  in 
the  six  months,  October,  1936  to  March,  1937,  were  almost  three  per  cent 
above  the  six  consecutive  peak  months  of  1929,  although  their  total  ship- 
ments in  1937  were  more  than  seventeen  per  cent  under  the  1929  total.  (56) 
Total  bookings  in  the  six  months  referred  to  were  equal  to  almost  three- 
quarters  of  the  entire  shipments  made  by  the  subsidiaries  of  the  Corporation 
in  1937. 

With  a  large  part  of  their  steel  requirements  for  1937  covered  by  the  end  of 
March,  and  with  mills  unable  to  promise  delivery  of  all  orders  in  hand  in  less 
than  six  months,  it  was  to  be  expected  that  steel  consumers  would  be  hesi- 
tant about  tying  up  more  working  capital  and  risking  unduly  large  inventories 
with  further  advance  buying. 

C.    THE  DECLINE  BEGINS:    APRIL  TO   SEPTEMBER  1937 

The  demand  for  steel  began  to  decline  rapidly  in  April,  1937.  By  September, 
bookings  had  dropped  more  than  sixty  per  cent  below  the  March  level.  (66)  But 
production  and  shipments  were  maintained  at  a  high  level  throughout  the  second 


13956  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

and  third  quarters  largely  on  the  basis  of  the  large  backlog  of  orders  placed  in  the 
winter  of  1936-1937.  Domestic  shipments  of  subsidiaries  of  United  States  Steel 
Corporation  for  the  third  quarter  were  about  fifteen  per  cent  under  the  peak 
shipments  of  the  first  quarter;  steel  ingot  production  in  the  United  States  declined 
less  than  five  per  cent  in  the  same  period. 

The  basic  factors  responsible  for  the  decline  in  demand  beginning  in  April  have 
already  been  indicated.     In  summary  they  were: 

(1)  Steel  consumers  had  already  placed  orders  for  a  large  part  of  their 
second  and  third  quarter  requirements  through  heavy  advance  buying  during 
the  previous  six  months.  Thus,  even  though  their  requirements  had  con- 
tinued at  a  high  level  in  the  second  and  third  quarters,  they  would  have  been 
obliged  to  come  into  the  market  for  but  little  additional  tonnage. 

(2)  With  consumers'  real  income  and  industrial  production  and  profits 
leveling  off  and  beginning  to  decline  in  the  second  and  third  quarters,  the 
demand  for  consumers'  and  producers'  durable  goods  rapidly  feU  off.  Thus 
steel  requirements,  both  current  and  expected,  were  declining. 

(3)  In  the  previous  boom  months  numerous  steel  consumers  had  optimis- 
tically estimated  that  their  steel  requirements  would  continue  to  Increase  in 
the  second  and  third  quarters,  and  had  placed  orders  on  that  basis.  Thus, 
when  the  expected  increase  in  the  orders  for  their  finished  products  failed  to 
materialize  and  demand  actually  dropped  off,  they  found  themselves  with 
unnecessarily  large  inventories  of  steel  on  hand.  (57) 

(4)  The  general  disappearance  of  expectation  off  further  price  inflation, 
bolstered  by  the  fact  that  after  March  there  appeared  to  be  a  general  stabiliza- 
tion of  steel  prices,  removed  the  price  incentive  for  speculative  forward 
buying.  (68) 

As  already  pointed  out,  there  is  little  reason  to  believe,  and  little  evidence 
to  support  the  contention,  that  the  decline  in  the  demand  for  steel  which 
began  in  April  1937  was  caused  by  the  advances  in  the  price  of  steel  in  March 
and  previous  mouths.  The  decline  would  almost  certainly  have  come  at 
about  the  time  it  did,  even  though  no  price  increases  at  all  had  been  made. 
The  changes  in  the  other  factors  determining  the  demand  for  steel  were  too 
great  to  be  offset  by  any  changes  in  steel  prices. 

D.  recession:  October,  1937  to  june,  1938 

By  the  end  of  September,  1937,  the  backlog  of  steel  orders  had  been  worked 
off.  (59)  Thus,  when  general  industrial  activity  collapsed  abruptly  early  in 
October,  the  demand  for  steel  continued  on  its  rapid  downward  pace;  production 
and  shipments  of  steel  by  December  had  dropped  precipitously  to  about  one-third 
of  the  September  level  in  the  case  of  production  and  43%  of  the  September  level  in 
the  case  of  shipments.  (33) 

The  decline  in  general  economic  activity  was  most  rapid;  in  the  last  quarter: 

(i)  Consumers'  income  (oh  a  seasonally  adjusted  basis)  declined  about 
three  per  cent;  (17) 

(ii)  Production  of  durable  goods  dropped  about  one-half;  production  of 
non-durable  goods,  one-eighth;  (6) 

(iii)  Industrial  profits  decreased  about  one-quarter;  (S6)  and 

(iv)  Stock  prices  fell  one-fourth.  (60) 

Thus,  the  factors  which  were  responsible  for  the  spring  and  summer  decrease  in 
demand  for  steel  were  greatly  intensified,  and  new  deflationary  elements  entered  to 
further  the  decline.  The  mistaken  optimism  of  the  winter  and  spring  of  1937 
turned  to  deep  pessimism;  advance  buying  and  reduction  of  the  1930-1935 
backlog  of  deferred  purchases  of  durable  producers'  and  consumers'  goods  turned 
to  postponement  of  buying.  Producers  of  products  made  from  steel,  who  in  the 
previous  boom  months  had  anticipated  <iontinued  rising  sales,  now  found  them- 
selves with  greatly  excessive  inventories  of  steel  and  steel  products.  (61)  Before 
a  recovery  in  the  demand  for  steel  could  be  expected,  these  inventories  had  to 
be  reduced;  in  the  meantime  the  decline  in  the  demand  for  steel  was  doubly 
aggravated. 

Bookings,  shipments,  and  production  of  steel  continued  downward  until  'the 
middle  of  June,  1938,  except  for  slight  increases  in  March  and  April.  (33) 

Meanwhile  steel  prices  remained  unchanged.  (33)  It  has  been  contended  that 
a  reduction  of  steel  prices  in  the  summer  and  fall  of  1937  when  demand  was  falling 
off  rapidly  would  have  cushioned  the  decline.  In  view  of  the  above  aiialysis, 
however,   this  seems  very  doubtful.     The  downward  shift  of  the  demand  for 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13957 

products  made  from  steel  and  the  inelasticity  of  their  demand  to  price  changes 
were  too  great,  and  inventories  of  steel  and  steel  products  too  excessive,  to  be 
appreciably  ofifset  by  any  changes  in  the  price  of  steel.  Moreover,  a  reduction  in 
steel  prices  by  leading  producers  might  even  have  intensified  the  decUne  in  steel 
buying  by  creating  anticipations  of  further  price  decreases. 

B.    RECOVEBT:    JUNE    TO    DECEMBER   1938 

The  decline  of  industrial  activity,  abrupt  in  the  last  quarter  of  1937,  continued 
for  the  most  part  throughout  the  first  half  of  1938,  but  at  a  much  slower  pace, 
especially  in  the  second  quarter.  Slight — and  possibly  seasonal — increases  in 
bookings,  shipments,  and  production .  of  steel  occurred  in  March  and  April.  (S5) 
May,  1938,  was  the  low  point  of  the  recession  as  measured  by  bookings  of  steel. 

In  the  meantime  the  average  level  of  steel  prices  remained  practically  un- 
changed. (33)  However,  the  period  was  marked  by  a  growing  hesitancy  in  regard 
to  the  future  course  of  steel  prices,  an  increasing  number  of  "rumors"  of  price 
concessions,  and  the  strengthening  of  expectations  of  price  cuts.  (62) 

In  the  middle  of  February,  a  reduction  of  $4  a  ton  was  made  on  cold-rolled 
sheets  in  order  to  bring  them  into  a  more  satisfactory  relationship  with  hot-rolled 
sheets.  (63)  N.o  noticeable  effect  followed  from  the  reduction  except  an  intensified 
uncertainty  as  to  the  future  level  of  prices.  (64) 

Although  steel  producers  in  the  latter  part  of  February  announced  the  continu- 
ation of  first  quarter  prices  into  the  second  quarter  (with  the  exception  of  some 
minor  revisions  in  extras,  and  the  recognition  of  the  $4  break  in  the  price  of  cold- 
ro  led  auto  sheets) ,  price  uncertainty  continued  to  grow.  (65)  In  the  second 
quarter  there  were  numerous  rumors  that  price  concessions  were  being  made.  (66) 
This  uncertainty  undoubtedly  caused  a  larger  volume  of  postponed  and  hand-to- 
mouth  buy'ng  than  might  otherwise  have  occurred. 

In  May,  1938,  revisions  in  classifications  of  sheets  and  strip  steel  were  announced 
for  the  balance  of  the  second  quarter  and  the  third  quarter.  (67)  The  reclassifi- 
cations involved  adjustments  in  extras  for  these  individual  products  and  were 
accompanied  by  a  reduction  in  the  average  price  level  of  these  products,  brought 
about  by  lowering  the  base  price  $2  per  ton.  (68)  The  announcements,  however, 
did  not  remove  price  uncertainty  and  rumors  of  price  concessions.  In  the  first 
part  of  June,  the  price  of  galvanized  sheet  broke;$3  a  ton,  and  further  concessions 
on  the  prices  of  other  steel  products  were  rumored  to  have  followed.  (68) 

In  the  meantime,  several  important  developments  pointing  to  recovery  of  steel 
demand  were  materializing. 

(i)  In  the  first  place,  the  large  inventories  of  steel  and  steel  products 
carried  over  from  1937  were  being  reduced  to  a  level  where  steel  consumers 
would  shortly  have  to  enter  the  market  in  order  to  meet  their  current  produc- 
tion requirements.  (69)  Undoubtedly  an  important  reason  for  the  low- 
demand  for  steel  in  the  first  half  of  1938  was  the  fact  that  steel  requirements 
were  being  met  from  stocks  in  the  hands  of  steel  consumers. 

(ii)  In  April,  1,938,  the  Federal  Government  announced  a  recovery  program 
consisting  of: 

(a)  The  desterilization  of  $1.4  billion  of  gold  in  the  inactive  fund; 

(b)  A  13>^  percent  reduction  of  member  bank  reserve  requirements  by 
the  Federal  Reserve  Board;  and 

(c)  A  "four  billion  dollar  pump  priming"  program.  Beginning  in 
March,  the  excess  of  Government  expenditures  over  receipts  rose  ra^Mdly. 
The  net  contribution  of  the  Federal  Government  to  consumers'  disposable 
cash  income  rose  from  $221  million  in  the  first  quarter  to  $536  million  in 
the  second,  (14)  and  expectations  were  that  the  rapid  rise  would  con- 
tinue throughout  the  year.  Moreover,  the  large  public  works  program 
announced  in  April  promised  large  outlays  in  public  construction  in 
the  last  six  months  of  1938. 

(iii)  In  February,  1938,  activity  in  residential  construction  began  a  rapid 
upward  climb.  (^4)  Residential  construction  contract  awards  (seasonally 
V  adjusted)  in  June  were  about  10  pier  cent  below  the  peak  figure  of  the  1936-37 
recovery.  By  the  end  of  March,  public  works  'construction  contract  awards, 
and  the  value  of  highway  and  grade  crossing  projects  approved  for  construc- 
tion, were  also  rising  rapidly.  (29)  The  outlook  for  heavy  construction  steels 
was  even  better  than  it  ha°d  been  in  the  1936-37  boom. 

(iv)  Manufacturing  production  in  the  first  and  second  quarters  of  1938 
leveled  off  after  the  rapid  decline  in  the  fourth  quarter  of  1937,  and  slight 
seasonal  increases  occurred  iif  February,  March,  and  April.  (6)    On  a  season- 


13958       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

ally  adjusted  basis,  manufacturing  production  in  May  was  only  about  three 
per  cent  under  the  January  figure.  Production  of  non-durable  goods  (season- 
ally adjusted)  began  to  rise  in  May;  some  of  its  component  items — such  as 
textiles  and  leather  products — started  to  advance  even  earlier.  With  indus- 
trial production  thus  leveling  off,  and  with  manufacturing  inventories  sub- 
stantially reduced  from  the  excessive  height  at  the  end  of  1937,  the  outlook 
for  the  last  half  of  1938  was  an  optimistic  one. 

(v)  Profits  of  corporations  in  the  second  quarter  of  1938  had  risen  above  the 
figure  for  the  first  quarter,  so  that  the  profit  outlook  was  improving.  (26) 

'In  the  midst  of  rumored  concessions  in  prices  and  uncertainty  as  to  future  prices, 
Carnegie-Illinois  Steel  Corporation  announced,  on  June  24,  1938,  price  reduc- 
tions of  $3  to  $4  a  ton  on  nearly  all  steel  products,  and  eliminated  the  basing  point 
differentials  at  Chicago  and  Birmingham.  (70)  Other  companies  announced 
similar  price  reductions  and  named  new  basing  points  in  the  major  production 
centers.  On  the  average,  announced  steel  prices  were  reduced  eight  to  ten 
per  cent. 

Undoubtedly,  price  concessions  and  uncertainty  as  to  future  prices  had  restric- 
tive effects  on  buying  in  May  and  early  June.  The  price  announcements  in  the 
latter  part  of  June  removed  this  uncertainty  and  served  to  bring  out  orders  which 
buyers  had  been  holding  pending  the  price  announcements.  This  accounts,  to 
some  extent,  for  the  fact  that  bookings  in  May  were  about  35  per  cent  below  the 
average  of  March  and  April.. 

The  price  reductions  came  at  the  same  time  as  the  expected  rise  in  industrial 
activity  began  to  materialize.     Between  June  and  December  1938: 

(i)   Consumers'  real  income  (seasonally  adjusted)  rose  over  5  per  cent;  (17) 

(ii)  Production  of  durable  goods  (seasonally  adjusted)  advanced  over  80 
per  cent  and  regained  60  per  cent  of  the  recession  loss;  (6) 

(iii)  Production  of  non-durable  goods  (seasonally  adjusted)  rose  20  per 
cent,  recovering  two-thirds  of  the  recession  decline.  December  was  about 
25  per  cent  above  the  low  point  in  April  (on  a  seasonally  adjusted  basis) ;  (6) 

(iv)  The  total  value  of  construction  contracts  awarded  (seasonally  ad- 
justed) almost  doubled.  (71)  The  December  figure  was  approximately  50 
per  cent  above  the  1936-37  peak  and  within  16  per  cent  of  the  1929  average; 
and 

(v)  Profits  of  corporations  more  than  doubled,  recovering  about  one-half 
of  the  recession  drop.  (S6) 

With  the  resulting  rapid  upward  shift  in  the  demand  for  products  made  from 
steel,  the  demand  for  steel- rapidly  recovered.  (33)  Domestic  bookings  of  sub- 
sidiaries of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  in  the  fourth  quarter  were  two-thirds 
above  the  recession  low  in  the  second  quarter,  but  less  than  half  the  1936-37  peak 
figure  in  the  first  quarter  of  1937.  Steel  ingot  production  in  the  United  States  rose 
80  per  cent  from  the  second  quarter  to  the  fourth. 

The  fact  that  price  reduction  occurred  at  about  the  same  time  as  steel  orders 
and  general  business  activity  began  to  improve  has  led  some  persons  to  believe  that 
the  price  reductions  were  primarily  responsible  for  the  recovery  in  steel  demand. 
Some  have  even  contended  that  the  steel  price  reductions  were  important  factors 
in  the  general  rise  of  business  activity  in  1938.  These  views,  however,  are  not 
supported  by  the  evidence.  The  basic  factors  responsible  for  the  rise  in  steel 
demand  had  begun  to  improve  weeks  and  months  in  advance  of  the  price  reduc- 
tions. Even  if  steel  producers  had  not  tit  prices  in  June,  1938,  steel  buying 
unquestionably  would  have  followed  about  the  same  course  as  it  actually  did. 

Steel  prices  held  strong  throughout  the  third  quarter  of  1938  except  for  a  break 
of  $4  a  ton  on  automobile  sheets  on  July  29.  (72)  Although  the  price  concessions 
were  temporarv,  substantial  tonnages  were  placed  by  the  automobile  companies 
for  their  1939  models. 

In  September,  1938  prices  were  reaffirmed  for  the  fourth  quarter  but  early  in 
October,  when  automobile  producers  came  into  the  market  with  inquiries  for  large 
tonnages,  sheet  and  strip  prices  broke  $4  a  ton,  followed  by  further  concessions 
of  $2  to  $4.  Similar  concessions  were  extended  to  other  flat  rolled  products. 
Although  price  concessions  were  withdrawn  after  a  short  time,  all  regular  steel 
consumers  were  given  an  opportunity  to  place  orders  at  the  low  prices.  (73) 

Inasmuch  as  most  buyers  realized  that  the  price  reductions  were  temporary, 
there  occurred  a  large  increase  in  bookings  in  October  and  November,  J938.  (74) 
The  effect  of  the  temporary  bargain  market,  however,  was  probably  not  to  increase 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13959 

the  total  buying  of  steel  in  the  last  quarter  and  the  first  few  months  of  1939,  but 
only  to  bunch  purchases  at  the  time  of  the  price  break.  To  the  extent  that 
buyers  took  advantage  of  the  price  concessions,  they  reduced  the  volume  of  buying 
in  the  following  three  or  four  months. 

F.    RECENT    developments:    JANUARY    TO    OCTOBER   1939 

By  November,  1938,  business  activity  began  to  level  off,  and  in  the  first  two 
quarters  of  1939  industrial  production  and  industrial  profits  declined  slowly  but 
substantially  while  consumers'  income  remained  virtually  constant.  (75)  The 
low  point  was  reached  in  April  and  May,  1939,  at  a  level  about  the  same  as  that  of 
September,  1938.  {76)     Two  important  factors  contributing  to  the  decHne  were: 

(1)  The  nation-wide  coal  strike  in  April  and  May;  and 

(2)  The  great  uncertainty  regarding  the  foreign  situation,  especiaUy  after 
early  March. 

With  the  coal  strike  settled,  and  the  foreign  situation  temporarily  receding  into 
the  background,  business  began  to  recover  in  May,  and  by  the  end  of  August  had 
reached  the  levels  of  November  and  December,  1938.  {75)  When  war  broke  out 
in  Europe  at  the  beginning  of  September,  1939,  the  advance  was  greatly  acceler- 
ated. Currently,  activity  in  many  lines  of  business  is  near  the  levels  of  the  summer 
of  1937.  Undoubtedly  a  substantial  part  of  the  recovery  since  September  1st, 
1939  has  been  of  the  speculative  inventory-building-up  variety,  induced  by  fears 
of  rising  prices  and  delivery  delay. 

The  course  of  general  business  activity  was  closely  paralleled  by  the  demand  for 
steel.  Seasonally  adjusted  bookings,  shipments,  and  production  declined  until 
May,  1939.  {76)  The  decline  was  aggravated  by  the  carry-over  of  steel  pur- 
chased during  the  price-concession  period  in  the  previous  October.  {77)  Prices 
of  steel  meanwhile  continued  steady,  but  with  numerous  signs  of  weakness  by 
April,  which  contributed  to  the  hand-to-mouth  buying  of  steel  at  that  time.  {78) 

In  the  first  part  of  May  when  automobile  producers  entered  the  market  for 
steel  for  their  1940  models,  a  sharp  break  in  steel  prices  occurred,  especially  in 
sheet  and  strip  products.  -{79)  All  buyers  were  given  an  opportunity  to  place 
orders,  and  a  large  volume  of  purchases  were  made,  at  the  low  prices  before  the 
concessions  were  withdrawn. 

It  seems  likely  that  the  price  concessions  of  May,  1939,  like  those  of  October, 
1938,  served  only  to  bunch  steel  orders  at  that  time,  without  significantly  affecting 
the  tonnage  sales  for  1939.  Certainly  the  lowered  price  of  steel  has  not  had  any 
appreciable  effect  in  lowering  automobile  prices.  For  steel  producers,  however, 
such  temporary  price  cuts,  which  do  not  significantly  increase  their  total  volume 
of  sales  over  a  six  of  eight  months  period,  can  only  mean  decreased  revenues. 

With  industrial  production,  consumers'  income,  and  industrial  profits  rising 
after  May,  1939,  the  demand  for  steel  recovered,  and  steel  prices  strengthened 
somewhat.  {80)  Then,  when  war  broke  out  on  the  first  of  September,  bookings 
bounded  upward,  and  currently  activity  in  the  steel  industry  is  almost  at  capacity 
levels.  Unquestionably  a  large  part  of  the  increase  in  the  demand  for  steel  since 
the  first  of  September  has  been  caused  by  fear  of  rising  steel  prices  and  delivery 
delay. 

G.    CONCLUSION 

A  careful  examination  of  the  record  shows  that  changes  in  the  demand  for 
steel  during  the  1936-1939  period  were  largely  determined  by  the  following  factors: 

1.  The  current  and  anticipated  levels  of  business  activity,  income  and 
profits ; 

2.  The  expectations  with  respect  to  steel  prices  in  the  immediate  future  as 
compared  with  current  steel  prices; 

3.  The  volume  of  steel  inventory  accumulated  in  the  immediate  past;  and 

4.  The  length  of  time  required  to  fill  new  orders  for  steel. 

Although  price  changes  and  anticipated  price  changes  affect  the  timing  of 
steel  purchases,  the  large  fluctuations  in  the  tot£l  volume  of  steel  production  dur- 
ing the  1936-1939  period  cannot  be  attributed  to  changes  in  the  levels  of  steel 
prices.  On  the  contrary,  the  evidence  compels  the  conclusion  that  the  influence 
of  the  level  of  steel  prices  on  the  total  consumption  of  steel  was  relatively  unim- 
portant. 


13960 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Appendix 


(1)     Tin  plate,  the  most  important  exception,  is  mainly  used  in  the  produc- 
tion of  perishable  containers,  i.  e.,  cans  which'  are  used  a  single  time. 

(S)     Table  2. — Midyear  population  estirhates  for  continental  United  States 


Year 

Popalatlon 
estimate 

Percentage 
Increase 

Year 

Population 
estimate 

Percentage 
increase 

1929 

121,626,000 
123,091,000 
124,113,000 
124,974,000 
126,770,000 

1934     . 

126,626,000 
127,621,000 
128,429,000 
129,252,000 
130,216,000 

0.68% 
0  71 

IMO 

1.29% 
0.83 
0.69 
0.64 

1936 

1931 

J936 """ 

0  71 

1932 

1937 

0  64 

1933 

1938 - ... 

The  population  estimates  are  those  of  the  U.  S.  Bureau,  of  the  Census.  See: 
U.  S.  Department  of  Commerce,  Bureau  of  the  Census,  Statistical  Abstract  of  the 
United  States,  1938,  (Washington,  1939),  p.  10. 

(5)     Table  3. — Business  gross  capital  formation,  capital  consumption,  and  net 
capital  formation,  l'dS4  to  1938  (millions  of  1929  dollars) 


Year. 

Flow  of 

producers' 

durable 

commodities 

(1) 

Business 
coa^truction 

(2) 

Gross  capital 

formation 

(l)+(2) 

(3) 

Business 
capital  con- 
sumption 

(4) 

Net  capital 

formation 

(3) -(4) 

(5) 

1924 

4,838 
6  368 
6  761 
6  993 
6  083 
6  891 
6,791 
4,012 
2,601 
2,779 
3,811 
4,683 
6,080 
6,987 
6,243 

3,408 
4,026 
4  325 
4  467 
4;  391 
4,681 
3,884 
2,481 
1,332 
1,166 
1,404 
1,742 
2,104 
2,726 
2,123 

8,846 
9,394 
10,086 
10,460 
10,474 
11  472 
9,675 
6,493 
3,933 
3,945 
6,216 
6,326 
8,184 
9,713 
7,366 

5,909 
6,112 
6,671 
6,657 
6,818 
7,134 
7,084 
6,951 
6,633 
6,315 
6,143 
6,162 
6,269 
6,437 

2  337 

1926 

3  282 

1926 

3,415 

1927 ' 

1928 - 

3,903 
3,656 

1929 : 

1930..... 

4  338 
2,591 

1931 : 

-468 

1932 

-2,600 

1933 

-2, 370 

1934 

-928 

1935 

1936 

1937 

1938 

Total  1924  to  1929 

' 

20,931 

Total  1930  to  1936    . 

—3,602 

The  above  figures  are  estimates  of  Dr.  Simon  Kuznets  of  the  National  Bureau 
of  Economic  Research.  See:  Simon  Kuznets,  National  Income  and  Capital  For- 
mation, 1919-1985,  (New  York,  1937)  pp.  40  and  48,  and  Simon  Kuznets,  Com- 
modity Flow  and  Capital  Formation  in  the  Recent  Recovery  and  Decline,  19S2- 
1938,  Bulletin  74  of  the  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research,  (New  York, 
June  25,  1939),  p.  2. 

The  figures  in  columns  (1)  and  (2)  of  the  above  table  represent  respectively 
production  of  business  equipment  and  business  plant;  column  (3)  is  the  sum  of 
columns  (1)  and  (2).  Cfolumn  (4)  is  the  total  of  depreciation,  depletion,  and 
fire  and  marine  loss  of  business  plant  and  equipment.  Column  (5)  is  the  excess 
of  column  (3)  over  column  (4)  and  represents  the  excess  of  production  of  business 
plant  and  equipment  over  consumption. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(4)     Table  4. — Net  earnings  of  corporations,  1919-1937 
[millions  of  dollars] 


13961 


Year 

Net  earn- 
ings 

Year 

Net  earn- 
ings 

6.419 
4,468 
'65 
4,380 
5,867 
4,998 
6,971 
6,774 
5,880 
7.666 

1929 

8,083 

1930 

1  366 

1931 - ..-. 

i  3  146 

1922 

1932 

16.376 

»2.379 

167 

1923 

1933 

1924 

1934. 

1925 

1935 

1,674 

1926 

1938 

3,903 

1927 

1937 

3,872 

1928 

1  =Deflcit. 

The  above  profit  estimates  were  based  on  federal  income  tax  returns  of  all 
reporting  corporations.  Net  earnings  are  defined — for  the  years  1919  to  193& — 
as  net  income  less  deficit  of  all  reporting  corporations  less  the  total  federal  tax 
plus  tax  exempt  interest.  For  1936  and  1937  net  earnings  are  equal  to  net  in- 
come less  deficit  less  the  federal  tax  less  dividends  received  from  domestic  cor- 
porations plus  wholly  tax  exempt  interest.  See:  IT.  S.  Treasury  Department, 
Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue,  Statistics  of  Income  for  1936,  Part  2,  pp.  24,  and  47. 
The  figures  for  interest  on  tax-exempt  obligations  were  obtained  from  Mr.  Ed- 
ward White  of  the  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue  in  a  letter  dated  July  14,  1939. 
Figures  for  1937  are  from  a  preliminary  release  (Press  Service,  No.  18-55)  of  the 
U.  S.  Treasury  Department  dated  August  23,  1939. 

(5)  In  addition  to  there  being  inadequate  profit  incentive  there  had  also  been 
little  necessity  that  business  make  capital  expenditures  in  order  to  meet  current 
demands  on  productive  capacity.  In  none  of  the  six  years  1930  to  1935  had 
industrial  production  averaged  more  than  four-fifths  of  the  1929  figure,  and  in 
the  low  year,  1932,  it  had  been  only  about  one-half.  See  Table  5.  Thus,  in- 
dustry's stock  of  plant  and  equipment  was  more  than  adequate  to  meet  the 
demands  on  it  in  these  years.  There  was  obviously  no  necessity  for  making 
capital  outlays  to  expand  capacity,  and  the  current  level  of  operations  was  so 
low  that  little  replacement  expenditures  to  maintain  capacity  were  required. 

(6)     Table  5. — Federal  Reserve  Board  Indexes  of  Production  {1923-95=100) 


Industrial  Production 


ally 
adjusted 


adjust- 
ment 


Manufacturing  Production 


(Combined  Index 


ally 
adjusted 


Durable  Goods 


Non-durable  Goods 


ally 
adjusted 


Monthly  Average: 

1929 

1930 

1031 

1932. 

1933 

1934 

1935. 

1636 

Jan 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May 

June 

July 

Aug 

Sept..., 

Oct 

Nov 

Dee 

Monthly 


13962  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWIOU 

(6)     Table  5. — Federal  Reserve  Board  Indexes  of  Production  {1923-25  =  100) — 
Continued 


Industrial  Production 

Manufacturing  Production 

Season- 
ally 
adjusted 

Without 
seasonal 
adjust- 
ment 

Combined  Index 

Durable  Goods 

Non-durable  Goods 

Season- 
ally 
adjusted 

Without 
seasonal 
adjust- 
ment 

Season- 

aUy 
adjusted 

Without 
seasonal 
adjust- 
ment 

Season- 
ally 
adjusted 

Without 
seasonal 
adjust- 
ment 

1937 
Jan 

114 
116 
118 
118 
118 
114 
114 
117 
111 
102 
88 
84 

112 
117 
122 
122 
122 
115 
111 
115 
109 
102 
90 
80 

115 
116 
117 
118 
118 
114 
114 
117 
110 
101 
85 
79 

113 
118 
122 
125 
123 
114 
110 
114 
106 
99 
86 
75 

112 
113 
113 
117 
120 
112 
122 
126 
114 
101 
74 
60 

107 
114 
123 
130 
132 
116 
118 
122 
103 
94 
74 
57 

117 
119 
120 
119 
116 
115 
108 
110 
107 
100 
94 
95 

118 

Feb             

122 

Mar 

121 

Apr.     .. 

120 

May -... 

116 

113 

July 

104 

107 

Sept 

109 

Oct 

103 

Nov 

97 

Dec 

90 

Monthly  Average.. 

110 

110 

109 

109 

107 

107 

110 

110 

1938 
Jan 

80 
79 
79 
77 
76 
77 
83 
88 
90 
96 
103 
104 

79 
79 
80 
78 
77 
77 
81 
87 
91 
97 
104 
98 

76 
75 
75 
73 
73 
74 
82 
87 

95 
103 

104 

75 
76 
77 
76 
75 
75 
79 
85 
89 
95 
103 
98 

56 
54 
5* 
53 
51 
50 
58 
64 
69 
83 
94 
92 

53 
54 
57 
58 
56 
53 
58 
63 
66 
79 
92 
85 

93 
94 
93 
91 
93 
95 
102 
108 
107 
106 
110 
114 

94 

Feb 

95 

Mar 

94 
91 

May """ I" 

93 

94 

July 

97 

104 

109 

Oct ... 

109 

113 

Dec 

108 

Monthly  Average.. 

86 

86 

84 

84 

65 

65 

100 

100 

1939 
Jan 

101 
99 
98 
92 
92 
98 

101 
1102 

99 
99 

100 
95 
94 
98 
97 

■99 

100 
97 
96 
92 
91 
97 

100 
■104 

98 
98 

100 
96 
94 
97 
95 

'99 

83 
80 
76 
71 
82 

193 

84 
83 
86 
84 
78 
85 

186 

no 

109 
110 
106 
108 
110 
110 
1  114 

111 

Feb 

111 

Mm""" 

Apr 

Apr. 

106 

107 

June 

108 

July 

106 

Aug 

1  Preliminary. 

See:  Survey  of  Current  Business,  1938  Supplement,  pp.  7-8,  March 
Reserve  Bulletin,  October,  1939,  pp.  914-916. 


pp.  14  and  19,  and  The  Federal 


(7)   Table  6. — Consumers'  Income  and  Outlay,  1929-1938 
[Billions  of  dollars] 


Consumers'  income 

Consumers'  outlay 

Year 

(current 
dollars) 

(1929 
dollars) 

(current 
dollars) 

(1929 
dollars) 

1929 

$78.6 
73.4 
63.1 
49.6 
45.9 
62.2 
,■16. 1 
64.4 
69.0 
64.2 

$78.6 
76.0 
72.4 
63.8 
61.4 
65.8 

76!  0 
78.1 
74.4 

$73.3 
69.1 
56.3 
44.1 
42.3 
49.7 
52.2 
58.9 
62.6 

$73.3 

1930 

70.6 

1931                                                      .          .  ..           

62.9 

1932                                                                  

54.4 

1933                                                                   

55.3 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13963 


The  figures  for  consumers'  income  (in  current  dollars)  are  those  of  the  U.  S. 
Department  of  Commerce  for  national  income  payments.  See:  Robert  R. 
Nathan,  Income  in  the  United  States,  1929-1937  (U.  S.  Dept.  of  Commerce, 
November  1938)  pp.  29-30;  and  the  Survey  of  Current  Business,  March  1939, 
p.  19.  The  annual  figures  shown  in  Table  6  are  sums  of  monthly  figures  reported 
by  the  U.  S.  Dept.  of  Commerce.  Consumers'  income  in  1929  dollars  was  ob- 
tained by  dividing  consumers'  income  in  current  dollars  by  the  National  Indus- 
trial Conference  Board's  index  of  the  cost  of  living  with  base  1929  =  100.  See: 
Survey  of  Current  Business,  1938  Supplement,  p.  11,  and  March  1939,  p.  20. 

The  consumers'  outlay  estimates  are  those  of  Dr.  Simon  Kuzneta  of  the  Na- 
tional Bureau  of  Economic  Research.  See:  Simon  Kuznets,  National  Income 
and  Capital  Formation,  1919-1935  (New  York,  1937)  p.  85.  The  figures  for  1934- 
1937  were  reported  by  Dr.  Alvin  Han=>en  before  the  Temporary  National  Eco- 
nomic Committee  on  May  16,  1939. 

{8)  For  an  exhaustive  study  of  the  demand  for  automobiles  see:  C.  F.  Roos 
and  Victor  von  Szeliski,  "Factors  Governing  Changes  in  Domestic  Automobile 
Demand,"  in  The  Dynamics  of  Automobile  Demand  published  by  the  General 
Motors  Corporation  (New  York,  1939). 

(9)  See:  Roos  and  von  Szeliski,  op.  cit.  Chart  21  on  page  60. 

(10)  See:  Roos  and  von  Szeliski,  op.  cit.  Chart  15,  p.  53. 

{11)     Table  7. — Consumers'  Expenditures  for  Durable  Household  Goods,  1929-19S7 
[MUlions  of  1029  dollars] 


Year 

Consumers' 
Expenditure 

^^^oSfh^o^i^ 
Ooods 

Year 

Consumers' 
Expenditure 
for  Durable 
Household 
Goods 

1929 

5,910 
6,130 
4,490 
3,360 
3.320 

1934 

4,010 

4,670 

-    8,900 

6,330 

1930 

1931 

1936 

1932 

1937 

1933 

These  estimates  are  those  of  Mr.  George  Tofborgh  of  the  Division  of  Research 
and  Statistics  of  the  Board  of  Governors  of  the  Federal  Reserve  System  and  re- 
ported (June,  1938)  in  his  memoranda  on  "The  Prospects  for  Durable  Goods.". 

{12)     Table  8. — Gross  and  Net  Capital  Formation  Arising  in  Residential  Con- 
struction, 1924-1938 

[Millions  of  1929  dollars] 


Year 

Residential 
Construction 

Excess  of  Resi- 
dential Con- 
strueUon  over 
Consumption 

Year 

Residential 
Construction 

Excess  of  Resi- 
dential Con- 
struction over 
Consumption 

1924 

4,589 
.5,  218 
4,757 
4, 515 
4,268 
3,010 
1,865 
1.506 

2,544 
3,079 
2,518 
2,182 
1,854 
530 
-646 
-984 

1932 

600 
648 
695 
1,193 
1,965 
2,193 
1,949 

-1,867 
-1,899 

1925 

1933 

1926 

1934 

-1,838 
-1,214 

1927 

1935 

1928 

1939 

1937 

—226 

1930 

1938 

1931 

These  are  estimates  of  Dr.  Simon  Kuznets;  see  note  (3)  for  source. 


H— pt.  26 2.5 


13Q64  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

{IS)     Table  9. — Indexes  of  Rent  and  Residential  Construction  Costs 

[1929  =  100] 


Monthly  average: 

1929 _ 

1933.... ..-. 

1934 

1935.. 

1036 

Jan 

Feb 

Mar 

June 

July 

Aug 

Sept 

Oct.... 

Nov 

Dee 

Monthly  Average 

1937 

Jan 

Feb 

Mar 

iKiV/.'.'.'.".'.'.'..'.'.. 

June - 

July , 

Aug 

Sept 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

Monthly  Average 

193S 

Jan.. 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr..... , 

May 

June 

July 

Aug 

Sept....^ 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec 

Monthly  Average 

1939 

Jan.. 

Feb _.  . 

Mar... 

tl&yV.y//.". :.'...:. 

June 

July 


100.0 
69.3 
70.4 
76.4 


80.3 
80.6 
81.2 
82.5 
83.8 
84.3 
84.9 
86.2 
87.3 
87.8 
88.5 
88.9 


90.0 
91.5 
92.6 
03.6 
94.1 
94.7 
05.4 
06.3 
97.0 
96.8 
96.4 


95.0 
05.4 
95.1 
04.8 
04.6 
94.2 
04.1 
04.1 
94.1 
94.1 
03.0 
03.7 


93.7 
93.6 


Construction  Costs  Indexes:  Residences  (E.  H.  Boeckh  and  Associates, 
Inc.) 


100.0 
81.3 

Si'.l 


85.9 
87.7 
80.5 


86.6 
86.6 
87.0 
88.0 
80.1 
00.0 


03.6 
05.8 
08.5 
103.3 
103.3 
103.2 
90.0 
100.1 
100.4 
90.3 
00.3 
96.8 


99.4 


96.4 
99.1 
99.1 
97.8 
97.2 
98.5 
99.  C 
100.0 
100.0 
100.6 
102  1 

ino.8 


99.3 


99.3 
100.1 
99.3 
99.3 
100.6 
101.4 
101.1 


New 
York 


100.0 
04.6 
73.0 
67.9 


60.6 
70.4 
70.4 
71.2 
71.2 
71.9 
71.9 
72.6 
72.6 
72.6 
72.7 
73.2 


74.4 
75.8 
76  6 
76.5 
76.8 
83.4 
84.9 
85.1 
66.5 
84.1 
8.3.6 
83.0 


81.8 
85.1 
84.3 
84.3 
84.5 
84.7 
84.6 
85.4 
85.8 
86.6 
86.8 
85.5 


85.5 
85.3 
85.3 
85.5 
86.0 
86  0 


Fran- 
cisco 


100.0 
84.9 
101.6 
102.2 


104.1 
104.1 
102.9 


108.9 
109.2 
109.6 
100.0 
100.0 


i(a< 


113.4 
108.6 
110.6 
112.2 
112.2 
116.2 
116.2 
123.1 
122.5 


116.2 
117.7 
116.2 
116.2 
116.6 
116.6 
116.7 
116.7 
116.7 
116.7 
116.7 
116.7 


116.6 


118.1 
118.1 
118. 1 
118.1 
115.0 
115.9 
115.9 


St. 
Louis 


100.0 
70.6 
80.4 
83.7 


82.6 
8.3.8 
84.0 
84.0 
85.5 
85.5 
85.0 
84.0 
84.0 


88.1 
88.0 
80.2 
89.8 
80.7 
01.3 
90.6 
90.1 
92.3 
91.6 
90.9 
90.3 


89.2 
91.6 
91.6 
91.6 
91.4 
90.5 
90.0 
92.1 
92.1 


93.4 
93.1 
92,2 


100.0 
81.1 
88.7 
85.6 


83.8 
85.9 
87.0 
87.0 
86.4 
84.7 
84.2 
84.2 
84.8 
85.3 
87.8 


94.1 
96.1 
98.0 


103. 3 
90.4 
00.6 
09.9 
98.4 
98.4 
05.0 


05.0 
102.1 
102.1 
101.8 
100.0 
101.6 
103.1 
lot.  3 
10^.3 
103.0 
106.1 
104.3 


102.4 
103.5 
102.4 
102.4 
103.9 
105.  0 
104..^ 


New 
York 


100.0 
60.6 
69.8 
65.1 


68.5 
68.9 
68.9 
69.3 
69.3 
70.0 
70.0 
70.0 
70.0 
70.5 


71.9 
73.6 
74.6 
74.6 
74.7 
81.8 
82.6 
82.8 
84.2 
81.3 
80.7 
80.5 


80.6 
84.4 
84.0 
84.0 
84.1 
84.6 
84.9 
85.3 
85.7 
85.6 
86.2 
86.2 


86.3 
86.1 
86.1 
86.3 
Si;.  7 
86.7 
86.8 


San 
Fran- 
cisco 


100.0 

78.7 
06.5 
97.2 


98.8 
98.8 
07.7 
08.0 
98.0 
101.0 
101.6 
102.1 
102.3 
102.3 


9.7 


106.1 
106.1 
108.2 
110.2 
110.2 
110.9 
110.9 
120.7 
119  9 
112.0 
112.0 
108.1 


111.  3 


112.4 
114.5 
112.4 
112.4 
112.1 
112.1 
112.2 
112.2 
112.2 
112.2 
112.2 
112.2 


112.4 


113.6 
113.6 
113.6 
113.6 
113.6 
113.6 
113.8 


St. 
Louis 


100.0 
74.2 
82.8 
77.0 


76.2 
77.0 
78.2 
78.2 
79.0 
79.  Q 
78.3 
77.2 
77.2 
77.7 
78.4 
78.4 


81.6 
82.6 
82.9 
83.3 
83.2 
84.3 
83.5 
82.9 
85.6 
84.6 
83.0 
82.9 


83.8 
87.6 
87.6 
87.6 
87.3 
87.? 
87.8 
89.3 
89.3 
90.5 
91.  S 
91.8 


96.4 
96.4 
96.0 
06.0 
96.0 
95.6 
94.4 


The  rent  index  is  that  of  the  National  Industrial  Conference  Board  with  base 
shifted  from  1923  to  1929.  See:  Survey  of  Current  Business,  193S  Supplement, 
p.  11,  March  1939,  p.  20  and  September  1939,  p.  20.  The  construction  costs 
indexes  are  those  of  E.  H.  Boeckh  and  Associates,  Inc.,  and  are  based  on  actual 
contractors'  records  of  wages  and  material  costs.  The  base  of  the  Boeckh  indexes 
has  been  shifted  to  1929.  See:  Survey  of  Current  Business,  193S  SuppleJtient, 
p.  22,  Ma.ch  1939,  p.  22  and  September  1939,  p.  22. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13965 


(14)  See:  "Explanation  of  Method  of  Compiling  Net  Contribution,"  a  memo- 
randum of  the  Division  of  Research  and  Statistics  of  the  Board  of  Governors  of 
the  Federal  Reserve  System  dated  February  10,  1939. 

(15)  The  gross  federal  debt  outstanding  at  the  end  of  March  1933  was  21.4 
billion  dollars.  By  the  end  of  December  1935  it  had  increased  9.2  billions  to  a 
total  of  30.6  billion  dollars.  See:  Survey  of  Current  Business,  1936  Supplement, 
p.  55,  and  1938  Supplement,  p.  65. 

{16)  The  Standard  Statistics  Co.,  Inc.  combined  index  of  the  prices  of  420 
industrial,  railroad  and  public  utility  stocks  stood  at  64.6  (1926=100)  in  March, 
1935.  In  March,  1936  the  index  stood  at  108.7,  ail  increase  of  about  70  per  cent 
over  March,   1935.     See:   Survey  of  Current  Business,  1938  Supplement,  p.   77. 


(17)     Table  10. 


■Monthly  indexes  of  consumers'  income,  1936-1939 
[1929=100] 


Jan.-.- ' - 

Feb 

Mm- ..1 . 

May - r.- 

June..,-. - -.. 

July 

Aug... ■. 

Sept 

Oct—.. 

Nov........ _ 

Dec 

Monthly  Average 

1937 

Jan 

Feb :.... 

Mar.. 

Apr.... 

May 

June 

July. - 

Aug 

Sept 

Oct 

Nov 

Dec... 

Monthly  Average 

193S 

Jan 

Feb 

Mar 

Apr 

May 

June 

July 

Aug 

Sept 

Oct 

Nov ,.: 

Dec _ 

Monthly  Average 

1939 

Jan.._ . 

Feb.... 

Mar... 

Apr 

May*. 

June 

July _II.I.-..II 


U.  S.  Dept.  of  Commerce 
Index  of  Monthly  In- 
come Payments 


Adjusted 
for 


variation 
(1) 


88.3 
88.2 
88.8 
89.3 
90.2 
88.7 
88.0 
86.5 
85.8 


83.5 
82.6 
82.7 
81.4 
80.4 
80.7 
80.7 
81.5 
82.0 
82.1 
83.2 
84.1 


84.2 
82.7 
82.8 
.83^.5 


Unadjusted 


seasonal 
variation 


76.9 
72.1 
76.2 
77.9 
75.1 
92.1 
86.3 
75.9 
83.3 


84.6 
79.2 
86.6 

83!  7 
92.2 
89.8 
83.8 
91.8 
92.2 
82.5 
98.6 


83.7 
76.0 
81.4 
81.6 
76.7 
82.3 
81.0 
76.1 
83.5 
86.3 
80.9 
90.9 


84.3 
77.8 
84.3 
83.0 
79.6 
87.2 
83.9 


Cost  of 
Living 


83.8 
83.4 
83.1 


85.8 
85.6 
85.7 
86.0 


87.1 
87.8 
88.2 
88.7 
88.8 

88.9 

89!  4 

88!  5 


87.4 
86.6 
86.6 
86.7 
86.4 
86.6 
86.4 
85.8 
85.8 
85.7 
85.5 
85.7 


85.3 
85.0 
84.8 
84.9 
84.7 
84.6 
84.8 


Real  Consumers' 
Income 


Adjusted 

for 
seasonal 
variation 

(4) 


90.2 
91.0 
92.3 
92.4 
92.7 
107.3 
101.9 
95.9 
95.0 
96.4 
9T.9 
99.9 


96.7 


98.4 
99.2 
100.6 
100.1 
99.4 
100.0 
100.6 
101.5 
99.3 
98.4 
97.3 
96.9 


95.5 
93.9 
93.1 
93.2 

95!  0 

95.6 
95.8 
97.3 
98.1 


98.2 
99.3 

97.4 
97.8 
98.7 


Unadjusted 

for 

seasonal 

variation 

(6) 


91.8 
86.5 
91.7 
93.5 

108!  4 

101.4 
88.8 
97.1 

101.3 
94.0 

116. 3 


6.7 


97.5 
90.9 
98.6 
100.1 
94.4 
103.8 
101.1 
94.3 
102.8 
103.1 
92.8 
111.4 


95.8 
87.8 
94.0 
94.1 
88.8 
95.0 
93.8 

97!  3 
100.7 

94.6 
106.1 


91.5 
99.4 
97.8 
94.0 
103.1 
98.9 


13966       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Real  consumers'  income  was  obtained  by  dividing  the  indexes  of  monthly 
income  payments  by  the  index  of  the  cost  of  living.  For  the  indexes  of  monthly 
income  payments  see:  Robert  R.  Nathan,  Income  in  the  United  Slates,  1939-37 
(Washington,  November  1938)  a  bulletin  of  the  U.  S.  Bureau  of  Foreign  and 
Domestic  Commerce,  and  the  Survey  of  Current  Business,  July  1939,  p.  19,  and 
September  1939,  p.  19.  The  cost  of  living  index  is  that  of  the  National  Indus- 
trial Conference  Board  with  base  shifted  to  1929.  See;  Survey  of  Current  Busi- 
ness, 1938  Supplement,  p.  11,  March  1939,  p.  20,  and  September  1939,  p.  20. 

Note.— The  U.  S.  Department  of  Commerce  inda^  of  monthly  income  payments  has  recently  been 
revised.    See  Survey  of  Current  Butineis,  October,  lfi39,  pp.  15-10,  and  19. 

(18)     Table  11. —  U.  S.  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  indexes  of  wholesale  prices, 
1936-1939 

[1926=100] 


Date 

Grains 

Raw 

Materials 

Finished 
Products 

Semimanu- 
factures 

1936 
Jan          - — 

78.9 
78.3 
75.6 
73.9 
70.6 
73.0 

102!  4 
102.0 
102.1 
102.9 
109.0 

113.0 
111.5 
113.2 
119.2 
113.9 
105.7 
105.2 
92.0 
91.9 
77.0 
69.2 
71.5 

75.0 
73.0 
69.0 
66.0 
02.3 
62.7 
68.3 
53.4 
53.0 
50.8 
50.9 
64.4 

66.3 
64.7 
54.5 
55.2 
69.6 
68.2 
62.3 

78.1 
79.1 
77.4 
77.0 
75.8 
77.6 
79.8 
81.5 
81.8 
82.1 
83.1 
85.6 

88.1 
88.3 
90.1 
&8.7 
87.1 
86.1 
86.5 
84.8 
84.4 
80.7 
77.2 
75.4 

74.9 
73.6 
73.2 
71.3 
70.7 
71.4 
72.3 
71.4 
72.0 
70.9 
71.6 
70.9 

70.9 
70.9 
70.1 
68.5 
68.9 
67.7 
67.8 

82.4 
82.2 
81.3 
81.6 
80.5 
SO.  7 
81.6 
82.4 
82.3 
82.0 
82.6 
83.8 

84.9 
85.4 
86.4 
87.4 
87.5 
87.7 
88.8 
89. 0 
89.1 
88.1 
86.7 
85.3 

84.3 
83.3 
83.4 
82.7 
82.1 
82.2 
82.5 
81.8 
81.8 
81.1 
80.5 
80.2 

80.0 
80.2 
80.2 
80.1 
79.9 
79.6 
79.2 

74.8 

Feb 

Mar      .- - 

74.4 

74.6 

£f£^:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::.. 

74.1 

73.9 

July      - 

75.2 

74.6 

75.9 

Oct - 

76.2 

Nov - 

78.6 

Dec 

82  3 

1937 
Jan                                    .                

85.4 

Feb            .            .          - 

85.5 

Mar             .  ..  .  :..:.—.: — 

89.6 

89.6 

^^  ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 

87.6 

June     -■ 

86.8 

July      - 

87.0 

86.6 

85.3 

Ota.::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::""::::": 

82.6 

Nov..    ...- 

79.8 

Dec 

77.7 

1938 
Jan 

76  9 

Feb 

76.1 

Mar 

75.6 

Apr 

76.3 

Xy            ::    : :. 

75.4 

June                                                           .       -  . 

74.1 

July           .                                     

74.3 

Aug              .           .              

74.4 

scm       :  : :     .::::..  ..: 

74.7 

oepi. ................ ......  .^^^... 

75.9 

Nov        - 

76.2 

75.2 

1939 
Jan 

74.9 

Feb 

74.4 

Mar - 

74.6 

Apr 

74.4 

ifii 

74.3 

June 

74.1 

July 

74.4 

I 

See:  Survey  of  Current  Businett,  1938  Supplement,  p.  12,  March  1939,  p.  20,  and  September 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       13967 

(19)  The  following  statement  appeared  in  The  Iron  Age,  November  19,  1936, 
p.  56: 

"Most  (automobile)  companies  have  already  made  sales  predictions  for  the 
1937  model  year,  but  if  the  piesent  trend  is  continued  these  predictions  will  have 
to  be  revised  .  .  .  and,  if  upward  revision  in  sales  budgets  continues,  the  industry 
may  possibly  eclips"e  the  5,621,000  record  number  of  units  set  in  1929." 

See  also:  The  Iron  Age,  Sept.  3,  1936,  p.  53;  Nov.  12,  1936,  pp.  57  and  91;  and 
Jan.  7,  1937,  pp.  73  and  98. 

(SO)     See:  Roos  and  von  Szeliski,  op.  cit.,  Chart  32,  p.  74,  and  Chart  35,  p.  81. 

{21)  See:  The  Iron  Age,  Nov.  12,  1936,  p.  57;  Nov.  19,  1936,  p.  56;  Dec.  10, 
1936,  p.  55;  Dec.  17,  1936,  p.  54;  and  Steel,  Nov.  9,  1936,  p.  33;  and  Nov.  16, 
1936,  p.  31. 

{22)  See  statements  in  The  Iron  Age,  Dec.  3,  1936,  p.  62;  Dec.  24,  1936,  p.  47; 
Dec.  31,  1936,  p.  63,  and  Jan.  7,  1937,  p.  99;  and  in  Steel,  Dec.  14,  1936,  p.  24. 


{23) 


Table  12 


Quarter 

Billed  Sales 

of  Electric 

Ranges 

($000) 

(1) 

Sales  of  Elec- 
tric Household 
Refrigerators 
(number) 

(2) 

Vacuum  Clean- 
ers (Floor 
Type)  Ship- 
ments of 
(number) 

:3) 

1935 
IV                                                         J 

$3,542 

4, 142 
6,796 
4.892 
4, 852 

6,941 
9,  093 
6,130 
3,651 

5,420 

-    5,434 

4,115 

3,310 

6.596 
G,  359 

166, 540 

570,959 
870, 600 
392, 123 
245,853 

769, 705 
936, 045 
396, 137 
267,  138 

424,410 
496,869 
243,876 
114, 047 

600,280 
803, 018 

206, 206 
274,818 

1936 
I       

n    

Ill : 

IV --- - 

325.611 

352,956 
368  590 

li    :   : 

III     

282,261 
281,409 

277,436 
'    228  139 

IV    

1938 
I 

li 

lii 

'    207,511 
280,977 

IV    

1939 
!...,„. 

II 

272,  202 

(1)  Compiled  by  the  National  Electrical  Mamifucturers'  Association  from  data  furnishedby  its  i 
Figures  represent  practically  all  of  the  output  of  electric  ranges: 

(2)  Compiled  by  the  Edison  Electric  Institute,  b.Hsed  on  estimates  of  the  National  Electrical  Manufaeturera' 
Association  covering  reports  of  its  members  only. 

(3)  Compiled  by  the  Vacuum  Cleaners  Manufacturers'  ^iMociaiion,  representing  practically  the  entire 
industry. 


13968 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


These   three  series  are  reported  on  monthly  basis  in  ^^^^  Purvey  of  Current 
Business,  1938  Supplement,  p   141,  March  1939,  p.  51,  and  September  1939,  p.  51. 

(24)   Table  13. -^Construction  Activity  Indexes 


Federal  Reserve  Board  Indexes  of  Value 

of   Construction   ContracU   Awarded 

(1923-25=100) 

Date 

Adjusted  for 
seasonal  variation 

Unadjusted  for 
seasonal  variation 

Resi- 
dential 

Total 

Resi- 
dential 

Total 

87 

117 

87 

117 

1936 

62 

21 

60 

Jan - - - --- 

26 

52 

22 

45 

Feb - 

26 

47 

28 

47 

Mar.. - -— 

30 

47 

35 

53 

fe;:;;:::::;:::;:::;:::;:;::::;::::::::::::::::::::;:::::::: 

32 

46 
52 

38 
39 

56 
60 

Juhe .— - 

59 

46 

65 

July 

62 

46 

65 

Aug 

59 

47 

60 

Sept - - --- 

43 

57 

41 

54 

Oct - - ' 

40 

68 

39 

51 

Nov - 

Dec - <•■ 

45 

66 

38 

53 

37 

65 

37 

56 

1937 

45 

63 

37 

51 

Jan - - 

47 

62 

42 

54 

Feb - - ;- 

66 

47 

56 

Mar -- -  - 

44 

63 

51 

61 

i^:::::::::::::::::::::;:::::::::::::;;:::::;;::"::::::::: 

44 
42 

56 
61 

62 
47 

72 

June - - - 

44 

67 

45 

75 

July... ^ 

40 

62 

40 

66 

Aug , 

37 

56 

37 

56 

Sept 

52 

35 

49 

Oct - - :--  - 

56 

31 

50 

g^    :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ""-- 

30 

61 

25 

49 

41 

59 
52 

41 
22 

59 

1938 

42 

Jan - 

32 

51 

28 

44 

Feb - - - - 

33 

46 

35 

46 

Mar.. - r 

37 

52 

43 

59 

37 

51 
54 

44 
46 

61 
63 

June - - - 

49 

59 

49 

65 

July - 

66 

62 

69 

Aug..... - - 

56 

78 

56 

79 

Sept 

67 

82 

56 

78 

Oct - - 

96 

54 

85 

Nov 

57 

96 

48 

77 

44 

64 

44 
45 

64 

1939 

86 

70 

Jan 

73 

61 

63 

Feb - 

6J 

6C 

69 

Mar - 

5i 

6 

« 

76 

^:::::::;;:;:::::::;:;::::;:::v::::::::;::::::;:::::::::: 

6. 

6. 
i               6, 

J               65 
)               64 

■73 

June - 

e 

2               6 

J               6! 

73 

July 

1              'T 

J              '6- 

177 

Aug 

1 

T^ 

I  Preliminary. 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13969 


The  Federal  Reserve  Board  indexes  are  based  on  reports  of  the  F.  W.  Dodge 
Corporation  for  37  states  east  of  the  Rocky  Mountains.     See:  Survey  of  Current 


Business,  1938  Supplement,  p.  16,  and  March  1939,  p.  21 
from  The  Federal  Reserve  Bulletin,  October  1939,  p.  914. 

(^5)     Tablk  14. — Railroad  activity 


Data  for 


Federal  Reserve 
Board  Indexes  of 
Freight  Car  Load- 
ings (Combined 
Index)  (1923-25=100) 


Adjusted 

for 
seasonal 
variation 

(1) 


Unad- 
justed 

for 
seasonal 
variation 

(2) 


Freight 

Car 
Surplus 

(OOO's 
of  cars) 


Revenue 


Carried 
One  Mile 

(Class  I 
Railways) 
(000,000's) 


Net 
Railway 
Operating 
Income 
(Class  I 
Railways) 
($000) 


Monthly  Average. 
1S35 


Mar. 


Apr. 


Api 

May. 
June.. 
July.. 
Aug.. 
Sept. . 
Oct... 
Nov.. 
Dec... 


Monthly  Average.. 


Jan.. 
Feb.. 
Mar. 


May. 
June. 
July. 
Aug.. 
Sept. 
Oct.. 
Nov.. 
Dec. 


Monthly  Average. 


Jan.. 
Feb.. 
Mar., 
Apr.. 
May. 
June. 
July.. 
Aug.. 
Sept. . 
Oct-. 
Nov.. 
Dec... 


Monthly  Average. 


Jan.. 
Feb.. 
Mar.. 
Apr.. 
May. 
June. 
July.. 


61 


1,491 
1,341 
1,370 
1,385 
1,377 
1,593 
1,709 
1,855 
1,659 
1,475 
1,436 
1,787 


21, 935 
26,296 
38, 130 
34, 709 
39,599 
34, 103 
26, 919 
42, 157 
57,  349 
75, 455 
54,224 
46,021 


41,408 


2,030 
1,797 
1,921 
1,856 
1,902 
2,164 
2,438 
2,429 
2,200 
1,977 
1,817 
2,127 


1,981 
1,648 
1,64» 
1,712 


2,118 


35,729 
33.562 
35, 152 
41, 493 
41,  797 
60,259 
61,  722 
64,637 
70,096 
89,809 
72,377 
70,606 


55,595 


38,867 
38,784 
69,881 
48,358 
44,239 
59,354 
60,558 
50,308 
59,305 
60,747 
32,441 
25,972 


7,144 
'  2, 122 
14, 470 

9,23T 
16,497 
26,001 
38,387 


'  Deficit. 

(1)  and  (2).  Computed  by  the  Federal  Reserve  Board  from  weekly  data  repofted  by  the  Attceialwn  of 
American  Railroads. 

(3).  Compiled  by  the  Association  of  American  Railroads,  Car  Service  Dkiition.  Data  cover  Class  I  rail- 
roads and  represent  a  daily  average  for  the  last  half  of  the  month. 

(4),  (5)  and  (6).    Compiled  by  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission. 


13970       CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(25)     Table  14. — Railroad  activity — Continued 


Federal  Reserve 
Board  Indexes  of 
Freight  Car  Load- 
ings (Combined 
Index)  (1923-25=100) 

Freight 

Car 
Surplus 

(OOO's 
of  cars) 

(3) 

Revenue 
Passengers 

Carried 
One  Mile 

(Class  I 
Railways) 
(000,000's) 

(4) 

Net 
Railway 
Operating 
Income 
(Class  I 
Railways) 
($000) 

(6) 

Net 

Income 

(Class  I 

Railways) 

($010) 

(6) 

Date 

Adjuited 

for    ^ 

seasonal 

variation 

(1) 

Unad- 
justed 

for 
seasonal 
variation 

(2) 

1938 
Auk 

62 
64 
68 
69 
69 

63 
71 
75 
70 
64 

229 
169 
144 
175 
221 

1,976 

l!662 
1,664 
1,028 

45, 377 
50,362 
68,566 
49,  665 
49, 373 

1,097 

Sent 

6,277 
24  068 

Oct :"" 

Nov 

Dec 

C2 

C2 

257 

1,803 

30,996 

I  10,  338 

1939 
Jan 

69 
67 
66 
60 
62 
67 
69 

63 
62 
63 
68 
62 
b7 
70 

218 
209 
202 
265 
211 
175 
166 

1,790 
1,555 
1,618 
1,681 
1,725 

32, 891 
18, 591 
34,317 
15,267 
25, 101 
39,096 
49.  012 

'  8, 721 

Feb     

Mar 

127,896 

May 

1  18, 594 

'  1,685 

July 

These  series  are  all  reported  in  the  Survey  of  Current  Business,  19S8  Supplement, 
pp.  84-86,  March  1939,  pp.  37-38,  July  1939,  p.  38,  and  September  1939,  p.  37. 

{S6)     TABLfi  15.— Corporation  profits* 


Quarter 

Federal  Re- 
serve Bank  of 
New  York  (168 
industrials) 
(millions  of 
dollars) 

Standard  Statistics  Co., 

Inc.,  (119  industrials) 

(1926  =  100) 

Seasonally 
adjusted 

Seasonally 
unadjusted 

I 

1936 

$107. 9 
147.6 
124.7 
199.8 

170.0 
269.2 
217.2 
283.5 

248.3 
309.  0 
262.  4 
194.9 

74.0 
84.4 
61.  S 
187.0 

153.3 

49.7 
55.6 
61.5 
92.7 

7.S.2 
96.0 
83.6 
130.7 

109.6 
113.5 
104.4 
92.8 

38.7 
35.8 
32.2 
79.0 

'■<<.  7 

46.9 

II 

62.6 

Ill 

54.9 

IV - 

81.3 

I 

1936 

71.0 

II 

108.1 

in 

89.2 

IV : 

114.6 

1937 
I 

103.6 

11 ..     . 

T27.8 

Ill 

111.4 

IV 

81.4 

I 

1)38 

36.6 

II 

40.4 

Ill 

34.4 

IV : 

69.  S 

I 

1939 

65.  0 

li 

1  ..■        ;             1  08.7 

•  Data  arc  for  net  Income  after  payment  of  Qxed  char^Ci;  ,:ud  inxes.  All  of  the  abovn  series  arc  rcpor'o)  !u 
the  StiTvey  of  Current  Butinest,  193S  Supplement,  p.  64,  ^  Ir.r.^h  1039,  p.  32,  July  1939,  p.  32,  and  September 
1939,  p.  32.    See  also  Note  4. 

'  Preliminary. 


(Jdqtuiiu) 


CONCENTRATION  OF 


(jaqnmn) 
[  s8Ai}oinojOT[      pBOJijea 


ECONOMIC  POWER 


13971 


(jaqmnn) 


•-*  W  O  COfOQOO 


(000$)  (I  (Joop 
-jno  pno  aoopaj)   jnaui 


nU' 


(000$) 

II oa  poB  OY  (d  'H 

OOZ-I)      sjoiojM      D|J?09i5i 


CC00>0aCs»M»OO 


?5SS§?3? 


1  CO  Oi  C^  Ol  CO  <o 


(000'000$) 

,1  spooo  iBOijpoja 


01  (000$) 
iUaajqoBj^   i^ni^jJOMpooAl 


t^  «  02  C^  <0  lO  u 


(000$) 
t  ^jBjoa  pas  iBSnju^nao 


j^coojQ -^ys 


I        SOOS^C^CoSoa^coScDas 


(001  =  9261 

jS^namdiqg  9^bj3av 
/Iiq^noiv)  ijodxg  pnc 
ousemoQ   siooj,   en;qoBi\r 


OOOJOeO  ^cs  o 


o  cm'  »o  ic  CO  CO  o  r--'  CO  to  t^  t^ 


iiiii 


(00I=^S-K;6IiS?n9m 
-diqg  oSbjoav  iSiqauoj^) 
jaeradinba   iijpnnoj 


J2?5^S 


(000$) 

t  S9UBJO  pB9qJ9AO  OIJ!)09ia 


2iS?Jss| 


(000$)  t  jnamdmba  pas 


;_5SSJoCSSss 


(snox-?Joqg) 
,  aiBici     I99;g    pg^BOjjqBj 


ooco«-H^ccMocoas=o- 


gWOOMMO 


(000$)i3njAi9qsi8a)g 


ISBBil 


O'OCi00T}<Q0-«*'00c0^OC 


OCOM  coc 


(000$) 


jo    s.oOO)    isieipa    pajg 


?S§? 


SSSSSS 


,S<!;S5.5<)-So;^o 


:§    S 


13972 


(j^qmna) 
SJ80    jaSnessBj    pbojijbh 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

W00«0 I g 


(jaqmnn) 
saAjpmoooT;  peoJireH 


(jaquma) 
sreo     iqapii      peoairea 


|§S|| 


(000$)  (-"OOP 
-}no  puB  joopni)  jnaca 
-djnba    SniqoiiAiS   jaAiOj 


;sg8 


ss:sis;s 


iSi^i; 


(000*) 
Oa     PnB     OV    id    H 

ooz-T)    SJ050JV    oij^ooia 


r*  lO  cD«c  o 


(OOO'OOOJ) 

spoof)  [B0IJ}08[a 


((100$) 
yfj.'UiqOBJV    aai^JOAipoo^ 


i^^^^Sl^issIs 


SSSSSS:?? 


(000$) 
Xjbioh  paB  iB3nju}nao 
jrfAioj    'lUBaig       :!.'duin<i 


(00l=9Z6t       I 
S}n,»ni(liqg     BSvio&v       I 
Xiqinojv)    JJodxg    puB 
oijSdmoci   sioox  anigoBpy 


•o  o  00  >o  ri  r^  ec 


(OOI  =  K;-ZZ61  s?nam 
-diqS  e3BjeAV  ^ii{luoj^) 
luomdsnba   Ajpunoa 


iiisi 


t^  O  -^  OS  O  Cfl  »C  CO  0 
t~  O)  —  f- »  to  1^  00  t 


(000$) 
ssuBJo  pBaqidAQ  oix)09|a 


!Sc3SSf5 


ssiiggg 


(000$)  )ua[ndmba  ptre 
scnajsjis    3uinotJipnoo-Jiv 


1 1  s  1 1  §  §_S_i  §  i  I 


(suoj,-)joqg) 
0}BId      1884S      pe^BOuqBj 


3J5?5 


•>J'00OC>-Hdt-O'Ot~N« 


(000$)  anjAieqs  l3»iS 


3S3g 


§8SS8g 


(000$) 
ojtuinjtia     90UJO     13«>S 


iiiiiiS§i§gi 


(j;  -bs 
JO    b.ooo)       sjaiioa    laaiS 


-iQO!Ct~  ooor 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13973 

:2     »£■    »     <»     o     -g     ■Oo-    SS     S2     S     •:;     S    -2 
-a     _-^     --    -r    ^-     g     ^.^     £g     g       .       .     S     a 


^2  x«  x=  ^  ^  I    ^5  if-  I     ^    ^    _: 

ll  If  I  II  I  li  ^=  =  i  -  '^ 

•o£  OS  c  o  «  "  fe     §a  fflS  t;    w     ifl     „     3 

il  if  i  i  i  §  !"  ^U  '  H  II 

^s  l|  I  ^  ^  is^fi  :H.a  s  1^1  a  ll 

SIS  S'^  S  2  ^  S^^ti  Bt  g     sfeS     g     fcS 

ga  Sg  S  %  S  6n2>.g'  g_  o.sog     o.     "g" 


iilii  ili  i  P^i  1|  I  |il|i  ii 

6^-25 s  aie  d  |»°|'  •§!  1  ^-sg-ti  of 

as  sal  pa  a  ^pi  s:?  .§  s-^.a^^  i| 

£^5323  £a£  £     ceS.^     ot^^-  Sa2:2-    -> 

cS^'oS  ■oS'c  Tj    5"22g-    "^^ds  a§-o2.3     £§- 

t-Sa5  a  °  B  a    !:^„a    -"S.S  22na        Saj"? 


«i|Qo   fio02a'S|~?^s-s§S;^2fflOa1    »=3 


-^i"i|"rrr-^=|-ia-|-i=i=|=r 


13974 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


(28)  See  comments  in  The  Iron  Age,  Nov.  19,  1936,  p.  113;  Dec.  3,  1936,  p. 
118:  Dec.  10,  1936,  p.  114;  Dec.  24,  1936,  p.  85;  and  Dec.  31,  1936,  p.  89;  and  in 
Steel,  Dec.  7,  1936,  p.  114. 

{S9)     Table  17. — Business  and  Public  Construction 


Date 

Value  of  Construction  Contracts  Awarded  ($000) 

Value  of  Highway 
and     Grade 
Crossing  Projects 
Approved    for 
Construction 
(Federal    Funds) 
($000) 

Com- 

mercial 

buildings 

Factory 
buildings 

Public 
utUitles 

Public 
buildings 

Public 
works 

Highway 

Grade 
crossings 

Monthly  Average: 

1929                                

$77, 432 
61,360 
25, 925 
10,227 
8,281 
12, 650 

21)386 

3;  624 
10, 626 
9,673 

$43, 712 
.58, 393 
24,639 
6,300 
8,600 
10,  616 

$10, 065 
11,651 
15, 106 
9,832 
4,242 
4,639 

$77,  871 
80,251 
72,954 

41!  626 
52,087 

$16, 667 
241441 
41,073 
35.  172 
44.273 
52,  448 

1933 

1934 

1936 
Jan 

10, 810 
9,207 
12,202 
15, 197 
13,919 
15,021 
15, 821 
17, 326 
13,  653. 
16, 622 
12,826 
11, 976 

7,065 
7,761 
6,496 
6,284 
9,815 
9,468 
14,564 
10, 649 
6,002 
12.032 
8,854 
9,169 

8,707 
3,  885 
6,475 
7,319 
5,419 
9,146 
13,810 
4.422 
12.493 
11,198 
10, 694 
18, 104 

4,132 
4,843 
6,991 
3,079 
6,404 
7,672 
3,190 
14,188 
13,  547 
10, 931 
6,764 
16,  046 

35.699 
23,933 
30, 779 
33, 170 
25,967 
29,991 
40,083 
05,118 
63,  653 
75,117 
69, 645 
76, 387 

58,302 
60,076 
52, 083 
41,088 
33, 746 
26.208 
24, 996 
33, 711 
47,  679 
61,824 
77,  361 
78, 936 

Feb 

Mar                             

u^i ::::::::::::::: 

July .- 

$1, 776 

se^:::::::::::::::::::::::::: 

4,365 

Oct 

12.039 

Nov 

26.933 

Dec 

34, 972 

13,707 

9,013 

9,306 

8,149 

48, 212 

49, 659 

1936 
Jan 

"  16, 650 
12, 568 
17, 261 
24,  272 
18, 785 
21,910 
28,641 
21,963 
20,065 
21,989 
22,986 
23,156 

8,956 
13, 437 
18,411 
25,546 
12,  895 
10, 213 
19, 140 
14,980 
18,838 
18, 392 
14,075 
23,139 

17,926 
11, 939 
18, 106 
23,  753 
12,  773 
9,264 
27,  512 
17,946 
15,  735 
14,171 
18,029 
19,117 

12, 496 
4.342 
8,971 
6,264 

13, 706 

14,  669 
6,657 

11.246 
6.730 
7,991 
5,041 
4.207 

68,948 
34, 694 
44, 191 
49, 660 
60. 792 
70,717 
99, 103 
76,435 
68.767 
52.  861 
65.839 
42, 135 

72, 030 
80, 125 
82.599 
73.  596 
62,963 
53.  090 
50.400 
60,  476 
49.123 
46. 103 
42,093 
42,090 

35. 973 

Feb 

39. 022 

Mar 

40.283 

Apr 

42.011 

May 

40,  561 

July     

34, 081 

29.026 

26,  576 

oi?t.v:::::::::::::::::::::::::: 

23.615 

Nov 

20.233 

Dec 

17, 971 

20,761 

16,502 

17, 189 

8,517 

59,  612 

58, 724 

1937 
Jan 

21, 463 
22,295 
30,007 
28,540 
26,610 
24,488 
29,112 
29,590 
25,333 

18,'  855 
16,613 

37.028 
12,  609 
22,  248 
30,  051 
18,  539 
36. 822 
58,  601 
37,  875 
12.934 
12, 640 
13,504 
20, 940 

21, 788 
32,364 
20,256 
20,985 
10, 763 
29,  863 
49,992 
27,  455 
12,949 
15,  602 

17,  420 

18,  286 

6,533 
4. 952 
11,090 
8,163 
9,220 
10,827 
11,  255 
9,982 
6,  597 
9,179 
9,798 
8,305 

46,664 
27,264 
32, 221 
44, 757 
55,980 
70,  064 
52,  501 
63, 103 
62,873 
45, 982 
43,  983 
46,  475 

43,899 
44,472 

46,  856 

47.  081 
48,569 
49,263 
43,417 
40,606 
39.849 
39. 112 
39,  781 
41,683 

16  037 

Feb 

13.526 

Mm " 

12,859 

Apr 

13,688 

May..                                  .    . 

16,730 

July 

12:323 

Aug 

11,761 

Sept "■"'" 

12, 713 

Oct 

Nov 

10, 731 

Dec 

10, 443 

24, 754 

26, 141 

23, 144 

8,742 

48.489 

43,  716 

12,902 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        13975 

(89)     Table  17. — Business  and  Public  Construction— Continued 


Date 

Value  of  Construction  Contracts  Awarded  ($000) 

• 

Value  of  Highway 
and      Grade 
Crossing  Projects 
Approved    for 
Construction 
(Federal    Funds) 

Com- 
mercial 
buildings 

Factory 
buildings 

Public 
utUities 

Public 
buildings 

Public 
works 

Highway 

42, 149 
41, 407 
40, 636 
44,072 
51, 158 
51,  299 
53,137 
48,958 
43,  373 
38,  572 
36,231 
37, 677 

Grade 
crossings 

1938 
Jan 

•15. 40 
•13. 04 
•20.20 
•18.94 
•19. 17 
•18.  79 
•28.15 
•18. 33 
•13.96 
•24.17 
•13. 72 
•13.96 

•  6. 59 

•  4.92 
•15.68 
•11.47 

•  8.65 
•10. 68 

•  9.69 
•11.31 
•10.  74 
•13.79 
•10.53 

•  7.03 

48, 451 
5,149 
10,694 
9,373 
43, 699 
8;  689 
13, 431 
37,980 
26, 167 
21, 176 
19, 726 
44,312 

50,125 
26, 333 
49,005 
57, 631 
78, 533 
74, 832 
65,827 
88, 113 
83, 162 
92, 829 
70,  692 
114,075 

10, 433 

Feb 

11,392 

Mar 

13, 577 

May " :"■ 

:::::::; 

July                   

12,836 

11,416 

serrti' ::::::::::: ::::::: 

12, 561 

Oct   :.::::....:: 

12,112 

Nov 

13. 930 

Dec       

12,794 

Monthly  Average 

•17.99 

•10.09 

24. 071 

70, 846 

44,057 

12,188 

1939 
Jan 

29,509 
18. 518 
19,640 
35, 336 
21, 779 
9,968 
23,092 

67,002 
53, 115 
.58,010 
85,633 
76, 141 
73,607 
78,960 

36,294 
35,968 
34,969 
35,600 
40,769 
41,024 
37, 802 

13, 572 

Feb 

13,613 

Mar 

12,906 

Apr 

12, 107 

Sfay 

10, 224 

11.312 

July 

. 

11,504 

•  In  millions  of  Dollars. 

The  series  showipg  value  of  construction  contracts  awarded  are  compiled 
by  the  F.  W.  Dodge  Corporation  and  cover  37  states  east  of  the  Rocky  Mountains. 
The  coverage  of  the  data  varies  somewhat  from  year  to  year.  See  the  1938 
Supplement  of  the  Survey  of  Current  Business,  p.  169,  for  description  of  the  series. 
Figures  for  highways  and  grade  crossing  projects  are  those  of  the  U.  S.  Depart- 
ment of  Agriculture,  Bureau  of  Public  Roads,  and  are  condition  figures  as  of  the 
end  of  the  month  for  highway  work  administered  by  the  Bureau. 

All  of  the  series  of  Table  17  are  reported  in  the  Survey  of  Current  Business, 
1938  Supplement,  pp.  16-20;  March,  1939,  pp.  21-22  and  September,  1939,  pp. 
21-22  and  Standard  Trade  and  Securities,  Current  Statistics,  July  14,  1939,  p.  21 
(Published  by  the  Standard  Statistics  Co.,  Inc.) 

(30)     See  table  1,  and  Table  19  in  note  38. 

(Sl)  Throughout  July  and  August  expectations  of  near  future  price  advances 
were  becoming  strong.  See  the  statements  in  The  Iron  Age,  July  30,  1936,  p. 
55;  August  6,  1936,  p.  71;  Aug.  13,  1936,  p.  89;  Aug.  20,  1936,  p.  73';  and  Aug.  27, 
1936,  pp.  71  and  79. 

(32)  See  the  comments  in  The  Iron  Age,  Mav  28,  1936,  pp.  84  and  86;  June 
11,  1936,  pp.  80,  82,  85,  88  and  90;  and  June  18.  1936,  pp.  51  and  72.  The  follow- 
ing statement  appeared  on  page  102  of  the  June  25,  1936  issue: 

"Of  even  more  practical  significance  is  the  fact  that  fully  half  of  the  steel  tonnage 
booked  during  June  has  been  prompted  by  price  advances." 

(33)  See  Table  1. 

(34-)  See  Table  1,  and  note  38..  See  also  the  statements  in  The  Iron  Age, 
for  Sept.  10,  1936,  p.  93;  Sept.  17,  1936,  p.  93;  Sept.  24,  1936,  p.  75;  Oct.  1,  1936, 
p.  73;  Oct.  22,  1936,  p.  71;  and  Oct.  29,  1936,  pp.  67-A  and  70..  The  price  ad- 
vances early  in  September  were  effective  for  the  fourth  quarter.  Advance 
announcement  of  the  price  increases  undoubtedly  caused  some  protective  forward 
buying  in  the  last  half  of  September. 

(35)     See  note  18,  Table  11. 


13976  CONCP]NTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(36)     Table  18. — Composite  Price  of  No.  1  Heavy  Melting  Steel  Scrap 
[Dollars  per  gross  ton] 


Date 

1936 

1937 

1938 

1939 

13.47 
.     14.12 
14.75 
14.69 
13.39 
12.81 
13.29 
15.04 
16.45 

16.  es 

16.31 
17.10 

18.33 
19.27 
21.25 
21.02 
18  54 
17.28 
18.79 
20.43 
18.73 
15.89 
13.34 
13.46 

14.00 
13.86 
13.40 
12.40 
11.54 
11.32 
13.29 
14.51 
14.34 
14.21 
14.74 
14.88 

Feb;;v:::v:::::::::::::::::::::;:::  ::::::::: ::::; 

Mar :: :. ... . :::. 

Apr ^ 

May 

July...- 

Aug  . 

15  46 

Sept 

19  25 

ort": :::::::;::::::: ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 

Nov 

Dec 

Monthly  Average 

14.76 

18.03 

13.54 

■ 



The  above  steel  scrap  composite  price  is  that  computed  by  The  Iron  Age, 
and  is  an  average  of  Pittsburgh,  Chicago,  and  Philadelphia  quotations.  See: 
The  Iron  Age,  January  5,  1939,  p.  205.  The  figures  for  1939  are  for  the  middle 
week  of  the  respective  months,  and  were  obtained  from  current  issues  of  The 
Iron  Age. 

(37)  Employee  Representation  Plans  had  been  set  up  in  1934,  1935  and 
1936  in  many  of  the  leading  steel  plants.  In  the  summer  and  autumn  of  1936, 
the  number  of  employees  enrolled  in  these  labor  organizations  had  grown  greatly. 
Negotiations  concerned  with  the  question  of  wages  Were  carried  on  between 
steel  employers  and  E.  R.  P.  representatives  during  most  of  the  summer  and 
fall.  These  negotiations  and  the  possibilities  of  future  labor  difficulties  led  to 
widespread  expectations  of  a  rise  in  steel  wage  rates.  The  developments  of  the 
summer  and  autumn  of  1936,  can  be  followed  in  statements  in  The  Iron  Age, 
Aug.  6,  1936,  p.  71;  Oct.  22,  1936,  p.  71;  Oct.  29,  1936,  pp.  67-A  and  70;  Nov. 
12,  1936,  pp.  '2-78  and  91;  Nov.  19,  1936,  p.  76,  and  other  issues  from  July 
to  Novemoer. 

(38)  Appendix  T,able  19  below  shows  the  announced  prices  and  announced 
eflFective  dates  at  Pittsburgh  and  Chicago  of  several  steel  products  of  United 
States  Steel  Corporation. 

See  also:  Table  1,  and  the  comments  in  The  Iron  Age,  Nov.  26,  1936.  dh.  77, 
88;  Dec.  3,  1936,  p.  105;  and  Dec.  17,  1936,  p.  85. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13977 

Table  19. — Announced  Prices  with  Effective  Dates  (Subsidiaries  of  United  States 
Steel  Corporation) 

PITTSBURGH 


Date 
An- 
nounced 

Date 
Effec- 
tive 

For 
Ship- 
ments 
to 

Struc- 
tural 
Shapes 

Plates 

Soft 
Steel 
Bars 

Hot 
Rolled 
Sheets 

Hot  RoUed 

Annealed 

Sheets 

24  Qa. 

Galva- 
nized 
Sheets 

24 

Ga. 

Hot 
Rolled 
Strip 

Tin 
Plate 

Steel" 
Billets 

St'd 
Steel 
Rails 

100# 

100# 

100# 

100# 

100# 

100# 

100# 

Ba.'?e 
Box 

100# 

Gross 
Tons 

Gross 
Tons 

12-  1-38 
12-  1-38 

12-  1-38 
12-  1-38 
1-  1-39 
9-20-38 
6-24-38 
5-18-38 

2-18-38 
1-  1-38 
10-15-37 
8-5-37 
7-20-37 
7-  1-37 
5-12-37 
4-  6-37 
3-  5-37 

3-  5-37 
12-  1-36 

1-  1-37 
1-  1-37 
12-  1-36 
10-  1-36 
9-  5-36 
5-26-36 
5-23-36 

4-  1-36 
3-12-36 
1-  1-36 

12-  2-35 

3-31-39 
6-30-39 
3-31-39 
12-31-38 
9-30-38 
9-30-38 

6-30-38 
9-30-38 
3-31-38 
12-31-37 
12-31-37 

$2.10 

$2.10 

$2.25 

$2.15 

Not  Sold 
as  Such 

After  May 
18. 1938 

$3.60 

$2.15 

$34.00 

11-10-38 

$5.00 

::: :: 

""5.'35 

9-20-38 
6-24-38 

2.10 
2.10 
2.25 

2.25 

2.10 
2.10 
2.25 

2.25 

2.25 
2.25 
2.45 

2.45 

2.15 
2.15 
2.30 

10  Oa. 

Base 
2.40 

3.50 
3.50 
3.80 

3.80 

2.15 
2.15 
2.30 

2.40 

34.00 
34.00 
37.00 

37.00 

40.00 

5-18-38 

42  50 

2-18-38 

$3.15 

42.50 

10-15-37 
8-5-37 
7-20-37 

2.26 
2.25 
2.25 

2.25 
2.25 
2.25 

2.45 
2.45 
2.45 

2.40 
2.40 

3.15 
3.15 

3.80 
3.80 

2.40 
2.40 
2.40 

37.00 
37.00 
37.00 

42.50 
42.50 

7-  1-37 

2.40 
2.40 

3.15 
3.15 

3.80 
3.80 

5-12-37 
4-  6-37 

9-30-37 
9-30-37 

2.25 

2.25 

2.45 

2.40 

■5.'35 

37.66 

42.50 

3-  5-37 

42.50 

3-  5-37 
U-24-36 

6-30-37 
3-31-37 
3-31-37 
^30-37 
^31-37 
12-31-36 
12-31-36 
9-30-36 
9-30-36 
6-30-36 
6-30-36 
3-31-36 
3-31-36 

2.25 
2.05 

2.25 
2.05 

2.45 
2.20 

2.40 

3.15 

3.80 

2.40 
2.15 

37.00 
34.00 

1 1-24-36 

2.15 

2.80 

3.40 

11-18-36 

4.85 

12-  1-36 

30.00 

1.95 
1.95 
1.95 

2.60 
2.60 
2.50 

3.20 
"T26 

^5-36 
5-26-36 
5-23-36 

1.90 
1.90 
1.90 

1.90 
1.90 
1.90 

2.05 
1.95 

1.95 
1.95 

32.00 
30.00 

3-17-36 

1.85 

1.85 

28.00 
29.00 

3-12-36 

1.80 

1.80 

1-14-36 

1.85 

1.85 

11-27-35 

1.80 
1.80 

1.80 
1.80 

Prior  Pri 

36  Preva 

ling.._. 

1.85 

1.85 

2.40 

3.10 

1.85 

5.25 

29.00 

36. 37W 

12-  1-38 
12-  1-38 

12-  1-38 
12-  1-38 
1-  1-39 
9-24-38 
9-23-38 
9-20-38 
8-31-38 
6-24-38 
5-18-38 

2-18-38 
1-1-38 
10-15-37 

8-  5-37 
7-  1-37 
5-12-37 
4-  6-37 
3-5-37 
3-5-37 
1-  1-37 

12-  1-36 
1-  1-37 
1-  1-37 

10-  1-36 

9-  5-36 
5-26-36 
5-23-36 

12-31-35 
12-  2-35 
1-  1-36 

3-31-39 
6-30-39 
9-30-39 
12-31-38 

2.10 

2.10 

2.25 

2.15 

Not  Sold 

as  Such 

After  May 

18, 1938 

3.50 

2.15 

5.00 

34.00 

40.00 
40.00 

11-10-38 

5.00 

2.10 

2.15 

1 

9-20-38 

12-31-38 

9^30^8 
9-30-38 

6-30-38 
9-30-38 
3-31-38 
12-31-37 

'6^30^37 
y-30-37 

6^30^37 

3^31-37 
9-3C-37 
9-30-37 
12-31-36 
12-31-36 
9-30-38 
9-30-36 

3.50 

2.15 

5.35 

34.00 

2.10 
2.10 
2.30 

2.30 

2.10 
2.10 
2.30 

2.30 

6-24-38 

2.15 
2.40 

10  Ga. 

Base 
2.50 

3.50 

2.15 
2.40 

6.35 

34.00 
37.00 

37.00 

5-18-38 

42.50 

2-18-38 

3.25 

3.90 

42.50 

12-  3-37 

5.45 

10-15  37 

2.30 
2.30 
2.30 
2.30 

2.30 
2.30 
2.30 
2.30 



2.50 
2.50 
2.50 
2.50 

3.25 
3.25 
3.26 
3.25 

3.90 
3.90 
3.90 
3.90 

37.66 
37.00 
37.00 
37.00 

42. -50 

8-  5-37 
7-20-37 
5-12-37 
4-  6-37 

2.50 
2.60 
2.60 

"5.' 45 
""5.' 45 

42.50 
42.50 
42.50 

2.30 

2.30 

3-  5-37 

2.50 

3.25 

3.90 

37.00 

2.10 

2.10 

12-  1-36 

39.00 

11-24-36 

2.10 

2.10 

2.25 

2.96 

3.50 

2.25 

11-18-36 

4.95 

10-  1-36 

2.05 
2.05 
2.05 

2.70 
2.70 
2.60 

3.30 

9-  5-36 

1.95 
1.95 
1.95 

1.95 
1.95 
1.95 

2.10 
2.00 

2.05 
2.05 

5-26-36 

5-23-36 

1.90 

1.95 

29.00 
29.00 

11-26-35 

9-30-36 

5,35 
5.35 

Prior  Pri 

ce  Preva 

iling..._ 

1.85 

1.85 

1.90 

i.95 

2.50 

3.20 

1.95 

27.00 

36. 37  ^^ 

13978        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(39)  See  the  comments  in  The  Iron  Age,  Nov.  26,  1936,  p.  77;  Dec.  3,  1936, 
pp.  62,  105;  Dec.  10,  1936,  pp.  93,  96;  Dec.  17,  1936,  p.  85;  and  Jan.  7,  1937,  pp. 
66,  99,  183.  The  gist  of  these  statements  i^  that  bookings  in  December,  1936 
were  probably  the  largest  monthly  bookings  in  peace-time  steel  history,  and  that 
the  major  part  of  the  orders  were  placed  as  protection  against  announced  Jan- 
uary 1,  1937  price  advances. 

(40)  See  Table  1.  Peak  bookings  in  1929  totalled  1,590,793  tons  in  March. 
The  December,  1936  total  was  exceeded  in  only  three  months  of  United  States 
Steel  Corporation  history:  In  November,  1912  with  2,062,939  tons,  in  March, 
1916  with  2,064,472  tons,  and  in  November,  1916  with  2,357,161  tons. 

(41)  See  notes  20,  23,  27  and  29. 

(45)  Delivery  promises  of  the  Carnegie-Illinois  Steel  Corporation  on  most  sheet 
mill  products  in  December,  1936  averaged  about  3K  to  4>^  months.  That  such 
conditions  were  general  in  the  industry  may  be  seen  from  statements  in  The  Iron 
Age,  Dec.  3,  1936,  p.  97;  Dec.  10,  1936,  p.  93;  Dec.  17,  1936,  p.  89;  and  Dec.  31, 

1936,  p.  67,  where  it  is  pointed  out  that  backlogs  on  some  products  extended 
completely  through  the  first  quarter  of  1937. 

(43)  See  the  remarks  verifying  the  statement  in  The  Iron  Age,  Dec.  3,  1936, 
p.  62;  Dec.  10,  1936,  p.  96;  Dec.  24,  1936,  p.  47;  fend  Jan.  7,  1937,  pp.  66,  99,  and 
183,  and  other  sources  cited  in  note  39.     See  also  notes  22,  40,  57  and  61. 

(44)  Steel  prices  are  ordinarily  changed  only  at  the  beginning  of  each  quarter, 
with  the  announcements  of  changes  coming  usually  in'  the  last  month  of  the 
preceding  quarter.     See  also  the  comments  in  The  Iron  Age,  Feb.  25,  1937,  p.  91. 

(46)  See  Table  16  in  note  27,  note  21  and  the  statement  in  The  Iron  Age,  Feb. 
25,  1937,  p.  114. 

(46)  See  Table  1,  and  Appendix  Table  19,  in  note  38.  See  also  the  remarks  in 
The  Iron  Age,  March  11,  1937,  pp.  Ill,  114;  April  1,  1937,  p.  95,  and  April  15, 

1937,  p.  89. 

(47)  See  notes  20  and  23,  and  Survey  of  Current  Business,  1938  Supplement,  p. 
141. 

(48)  See  note  27.  See  also  The  Iron  Age,  Mar.  11,  1«37,  p.  133;  Apr.  1,  1937, 
p.  118;  and  May  6,  1937,  p.  116. 

(49)  The  delivery  situation  is  summarized  in  statements  in  The  Iron  Age, 
Mar.  25,  1937,  p.  85;  April  15,  1937,  p.  89;  and  in  Steel,  Mar.  15,  1937,  p.  103; 
Mar.  22,  1937,  p.  75;  and  Mar.  29,  1937,  p.  83. 

(60)  See  note  17.  If  Veterans'  Bonus  payments  in  June  1936  are  taken  into 
account,  consumers'  real  income  in  March,  1937  was  almost  seven  percent  below 
the  level  of  the  previous  June  (on  a  seasonally  adjusted  basis). 

(61)  Although  there  are  no  monthly  figures  on  business  outlays  for  capital 
equipment,  rough  interpolation  of  column  (1)  Table  2,  note  2,  by  the  series  in 
Table  16,  note  27,  indicates  that  business  capital  equipment  expenditures  in  the 
period  March,  1936  to  March,  1937  were  roughly  half  again  as  great  as  in  1935 
and  approximately  equal  to  1929  figure. 

(52)  The  U.  S.  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  estimated  that  in  December  1936 
there  were  258  industrial  disputes  in  progress,  in  March  1937,  760.  Man  days 
idle  due  to  labor  disputes  for  the  same  period  increased  from  2.1  million  to  3.3 
million.     See:  Survey  of  Current  Business,  1938  Supplement,  p.  39. 

(63)  See:  Survey  of  Current  Business,  1938  Supplement,  p.  85. 

(64)  For  example,  see  the  comments  in  The  Annalist,  March  26,  1937,  p.  482; 
April  9,  1937,  p.  554;  April  16,  1937,  pp.  604,  608;  April  23,  1937,  p.  650;  April  30, 
1937,  pp.  681 ,  682;  May  7,  1937,  p.  722.  The  fall  of  security  and  basic  commodity 
prices  which  began  in  February  to  April,  1937,  led  to  the  belief  that  the  speculative 
part  of  the  boom  was  coming  to  an  end,  and  that  prices  of  securities  a)id  basic 
commodities  were  going  to  adjust  to  a  more  stable  position. 

(66)  See:  Survey  of  Current  Business,  1938  Supplement,  pp.  56,  75  and  77. 

(66)  See  Table  1.  Total  domestic  bookings  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation 
in  the  six  consecutive  peak  months  of  1929  amounted  to  8,215,225  tone. 

(67)  No  data  are  available  showing  changes  in  inventories  of  steel  in  the  hands 
of  buyers  (producers  of  products  made  from  steel).  That  inventories  were 
becoming  excessive,  however,  is  borne  out  by  the  following  statements: 

After  stating  that  steel  consumers  were  building  up  inventories  of  finished 
products  and  work-in-process  beyond  the  level  required  by  current  sales  The  Iron 
Agexn  its  April  22,  1937  issue,  page  90,  commented: 

"This  leads  steel  sellers  to  the  conclusion  that  we  arc  approaching  a  time  when 
ultimate  consumers  must  be  given  time  to  digest  a  surplus." 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13979 


Throughout  the  spring  and  summer  similar  statements  pointing  to  the  growth 
of  excessive  inventories  appeared  in  increasing  volume  and  emphasis.  See  The 
Iron  Age,  May  6,  1937,  p.  103  (Some  stove  manufacturers  have  enough  steel  to 
meet  all  of  their  remaining  1937  requirements.);  May  20,  1937,  p.  93  (Steel 
jobbers  are  trying  to  reduce  their  heavy  stocks.)  and  p.  84  (Large  steel  consumers 
are  well  taken  care  of  owing  to  large  stocks  on  hand  and  heavy  orders  placed  but 
not  yet  received.) ;  June  3,  1937,  pp.  97,  98;  June  10,  1937,  p.  103;  July  22,  1937,  p. 
109;  Aug.  12,  1937,  p.  107;  Aug.  19,  1937,  p.  91;  Aug.  26,  1937,  p.  87;  Sept.  2,  1937, 
p.  88  (".  .  .  fresh  business  is  undoubtedly  being  affected  by  the  presence  of 
greater  than  expected  inventories  at  consumers'  plants.");  Sept.  9,  1937,  p.  107; 
Sept.  16,  1937,  p.  105  (Steel  consumers  are  liquidating  their  stocks  before  placing 
replenishment  orders.);  Sept.  23,  1937,  p.  101  (Inventories  almost  universally 
•are  excessive;  with  sales  of  products  made  from  steel  slowing  down,  liquidation  of 
heavy  steel  inventories  is  proceeding  slowly.). 

Table  20  below  shows  the  value  of  inventories  of  materials,  supplies,  work-in- 
process,  and  other  inventories  excluding  finished  products  in  the  hands  of  various 
steel  consumers  on  January  1  and  December  31,  1937  as  reported  by  the  U.  S. 
Bureau  of  Census  (See:  U.  S.  Department  of  Commerce,  Bureau  of  the  Census: 
Census  of  Manufactures,  1987,  preliminary  release  dated  April  15,  1939,  with  title 
"Inventories,  January  1  and  December  31,  1937"). 

Although  inventories  of  steel  are  not  reported  separately,  it  is  doubtful  if  they 
varied  significantly  from  the  broad  picture  shown  by  the  figures  below. 

Table  20. — Value  of  Inventories  of  Materials,  Work  in  Process,  Etc.  in  the  Hands 
o/  Various  Steel  Consumers  January  1,  1937  and  December  31,  1937 


Industry 


Value  of  Inventories  of  Mate- 
rials, Work  In  Process,  etc; 
($000) 


Jan.  1,      Dec.  31,     Per  cent 
1937  1937        Increase 


Agricultural  Implements  (including  tractors) 

Aircraft  and  parts — - 

Boiler-shop  products 

Bolts,  nuts,  washers,  and  rivets  made  in  plants  not  operated  in  connection 
with  rolling  mlllB • 

Cars,  electric  and  steam  railroad  not  built  in  railroad  repair  shops 

Cash  registers,  adding  and  calculating  machines,- and  other  business  ma- 
chines except  typewriters 

Cranes,  and  dredging,  excavating  and  road  building  machinery 

Cutlery  (not  including  silver  and  plated  cutlery)  and  edge  tools. 

Electrical  machinery,  apparatus,  and  supplies. 

Engines,  turbines,  water  wheels,  and  windmills 

Locomotives,  railroad,  mining,  and  industrial  not  made  in  railroad  repair 
shops 

Machinery,  not  elsewhere  classified 

Machine-shop  products - 

Machine  tools — — 

Motor  vehicles  not  including  motorcycles 

Motor- vehicle  bodies  and  motor- vehicle  parts — 

Refrigerators  and  refrigerating  and  ice-making  apparatus 

Ship  and  boat  building,  steel  and  wooden,  including  repair  work 

Stamped  and  pressed  metal  products;  enameling,  japanning,  and  lacquer- 
ing  

Steel  barrels,  kegs,  and  drums. _-- 

Structural  and  ornamental  metal  work,  made  in  plants  not  operated  in 
connection  with  rolling  mills 

Textile  machinery  and  parts. _ 

Tin  cans  and  other  tinware,  not  elsewhere  classified 

Tools,  not  including  edge  tools,  machine  tools,  files,  or  saws 

Washing  machines,  wringers,  driers  and  ironing  machines  for  household 
use 

Wire  drawn  from  purchased  rods 

Wirework  not  elsewhere  classified 

Foundry  products  (gray-iron  and  malleable  iron). 

Fnrgings  iron  and  steel,  made  in  plants  not  operated  In  connection  with 
steel  works  or  rolling  mills  

Hardware  not  elsewhere  classified 

Heating  and  cooking  apparatus  except  electric 

Machine-tool  accessories  and  machinists'  precision  tools 

Pumps  (hand  and  power),  pumping  eQuipment  and  air  compressors.. 


$101, 472 
24, 968 
17,958 

9,080 
26,930 

21,400 
17,  770 
8,872 
187,  236 
31, 839 

11,947 
110, 919 
62, 135 
34, 673 
"173, 139 
125, 804 
26,020 
24,962 

27, 019 
6,178 

31,  749 
13,758 
49,  593 
12,764 

6,115 
16,015 
15,640 
21,  577 

12,304 
27, 161 
51,096 
14, 163 
21,  508 


$112,388 
43,348 
21, 941 


37, 163 

27, 307 
24,  895 
11,455 
253,  693 
40,260 

21, 053 
135,  485 
71,817 
44,551 
214,  808 
128,211 
32, 765 
31,091 

31, 345 
0,814 


16,  251 
76,963 
■15, 488 


16,936 
17,460 
22, 946 

13,522 
30,  740 
61, 484 
16, 235 
27,567 


11% 

74 

22 


124491— 41— pt.  26- 


13980 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


(58)  See  Table  1.  In  the  last  week  of  April  steel  producers  announced  the 
continuation  of  second  quarter  prices  through  the  third  quarter.  The  Iron  Age, 
April  29,  1937,  p.  99,  made  the  following  comment: 

"The  principal  incentive  for  forward  buying  having  been  removed  by  the  an- 
nouncements of  a  continuation  of  present  steel  prices  through  the  third  quarter, 
an  easier  situation  prevails  in  the  steel  market." 

See  also:  The  Iron  Age,  April  22,  1937,  p.  94;  April,^9,  1937,  pp.  103,  105,  106, 
108;  May  6,  1937,  p.  116;  May  13,  1937,  p.  140;  July  15,  1937,  p.  95  (No  price 
advances  expected  for  fourth  quarter.). 

As  early  as  the  middle  of  July,  third  quarter  prices  for  most  steel  products  were 
reaffirmed  for  tlie  fourth  quarter.  (See  The  Iron  Age,  July  22,  1937,  p.  ^9). 
This  completely  removed  the  price  incentive  for  forward  buying. 

(59)  By  the  end  of  September  delivery  promises  of  the  Carnegie-Illinois  Steel 
Corporation,  for  example,  had  dropped  from  the  March,  1937  peak  of  six  to  seven' 
months  for  most  sheet  mill  products  to  two  to  four  weeks,  which  is  normal  when 
there  are  no  mill  backlogs. 

(60)  The  Standard  Statistics  Co.  Inc.,  index  of  prices  of  348  industrial  stocks 
stood  at  126.2  (1926=100)  in  September  1937,  and  at  95.2  in  December  1937. 
See  The  Survey  of  Cxirrent  Business,  1938  Supplement,  p.  77. 

(61)  There  are  no  series  available  showing  separately  (1)  inventories  of  steel  in 
the  hands  of  consumers,  and  (2)  inventories  of  finished  and  semi-finished  products 
made  from  steel  in  the  hands  of  producers.  However,  this  limitation  is  not  serious; 
excessive  inventories  of  finished  and  semi-finished  products  made  from  steel,  as 
effectively  reduce  the  demand  for  steel  as  excessive  inventories  (in  the  hands  of 
steel  consumers)  of  steel  itself. 

Table  21  below  shows  the  year  end  value  of  inventories  of  various  steel  con- 
suming industries.  These  inventories  include  raw  materials  (including  steel),  fuel, 
supplies,  work-in-process,  finished  products,  etc.  These  figures  are  the  revised 
estimates  of  Dun  and  Bradstreet,  Inc.  based  on  their  Surveys  of  Inventory  Trends. 
The  mid-year  estimates  for  1939  are  from  Dun's  Review,  Sept.  1939,  pp.  8,  10 
and  12. 


Table  21. — Inventories  1935-1938  for  Selected  Manufacturing,    Wholesaling   and 
Retailing  Lines 


Manufacturing: 

Iron  and  Steel  Products 

Hardware -.-■.- - 

Foundries '. 

Electrical  Apparatus  and  Appliances 

Machine  Shop  Products 

Agricultural  Machinery 

Automobiles 

Automobile  Accessories  and  Parts 

Wholesaling: 

Hardware 

Automobile  Equipment 

Plumbing  and'Heating  Supplies. 

Machinery  and  Erjuipment 

Electrical  Goods  and  Appliances 

Retailing: 

Farm  Im  plements 

Radio,  Electric  and  Gas  Household  Appli 
ances... 

Hardware 

Hardware  and  Farm  Implements 

Motor  Vehicle  Dealers... 

Automobile  Accessories  (Independents) 

Automobile  Accessories  (Chains) 


1935  Year 

1936  Year 

1937  Year 

1938  Year 

End  In- 

End  In- 

End In- 

End In- 

ventories 

ventories 

ventories 

($000) 

($000) 

($000) 

(.$000) 

$89, 093 

$111,366 

.$131,412 

$109,072 

203, 838 

238, 491 

290,959 

261,863 

34, 584 

329,  773 

395,  728 

557, 976 

423,504 

210,678 

143, 689 

172,  427  '- 

227, 604 

185,  497 

310,  559 

366, 460 

436, 087 

326,  193 

197,  704 

257,  015 

341, 830 

266,  969 

120,  328 

139, 581 

140, 977 

134,210 

99,730 

114,690 

125,012 

122,012 

57,019 

62, 151 

67,  745 

63,816 

68,692 

79,683 

94,  823 

90,  556 

59, 659 

80,540 

99,870 

77,  899 

34,080 

46, 272 

53, 676 

63,  569 

73,407 

73, 935 

92,419 

8.3,065 

196, 562 

202, 022 

218. 184 

214,  475 

44, 937 

49,913 

55, 902 

55.  119 

399,685 

398,  267 

561,  557 

463,  846 

29,843 

32,299 

36,  498 

37,  702 

29, 843 

33,  461 

37,811 

37,055 

$116,000 
266,000 


418,000 


172,000 
240, 000 
229,000 

139,000 
127,000 
67,000 
92,000 
86,000 

52,000 

89,000 
221,000 

56,000 
5.35,000 

40,000 

46,000 


See  also  note  57  and  the  source  quoted  there,  and  The  Iron  Age,  May  U,  1939,  pp.  57,  58,  58- A.  and  58-B 
for  other  inventory  figures.  The  inventory  situation  as  it  affected  the  demand  for  steel  is  also  discussed  in 
The  Iron  Age,  Oct.  7,  1937,  p.  97  and  p.  105  (One  fact  stands  out  prominently— stocks  in  the  hands  of  many 
consumers  and  jobbers  are  large  enough  to  last  for  many  weeks  at  the  current  rate  of  consumption.);  Oct. 
28,  1937,  p.  91;  Nov.  11,  1937,  p.  113  (Airto  companies  have  a  large  carryover  of  steel  not  used  in  the  produc- 
tion of  1937  models.);  and  p.  119  (Consumption  of  stocks  going  on  slowly.);  Jan.  20,  1938,  p.  93;  Feb.  24, 
a  1938,  p.  56  (.\uto  producers  still  have  large  inventories  of  steel.). 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13981 

{62)  See  the  comments  in  The  Iron  Age,  Jan.  27,  1938,  p.  75;  Feb.  3,  1938,  p.  91; 
Feb.  10,  1938,  p.  97;  Feb.  17,  1938,  pp.  98,  99;  Feb.  24,  1938,  p.  85;  May  5,  1938, 
pp.  86-87;  May  12,  1938,  p.  106;  May  19,  1938,  p.  68;  May  26,  1938,  p.  95;  June 
2,  1938,  p.  92;  June  23,  1938,  pp.  72-75;  and  Jan.  5,  1939,  pp.  73,  106,  110. 

{63)   See:    The  Iron  Age,  Feb.  17,  1938,  p.  54. 

(64)   See:   The  Iron  Age,  Feb.  17,  1938,  pp.  54,  98-99;  and  Feb.  24,  1936,  p.  85. 

{65)   See:    The  Iron  Age,  Feb.  24,  1938,  p.  85. 

{66)  See:  The  Iron  Age,  May  5,  1938,  pp.  86-87;  May  12,  1938,  p.  106;  May 
19,  1938,  p.  68;  June  2,  1938,  p.  92. 

{67)  See:    The  Iron  Age,  May  26,  1938,  pp.  88,  95. 

{68)   See:    The  Iron  Age,  June  16,  1938,  p.  81,  and  June  23,  1938,  pp.  72,  75. 

{69)  See  the  statements  in  The  Iron  Age,  Mar.  10,  1938,  p.  95;  June  16,  1938, 
.p.  81;  Jan.  5,  1939,  pp.  73,  106;  July  21,  1938,  p.  70.     See  also  note  61. 

{70)  See  especially  the  article  by  C.  E.  Wright,  "Basing  Point  Changes  May 
Alter  Industrial  Map  of  the  United  States,"  in  The  Iron  Age,  July  7,  1938,  pp. 
84-D,  et  seq.,  and  in  the  same  journal,  June  30,  1938,  pp.  60-63.  See  also:  July 
7,  1938,  p.  86;  July  14,  1938,  p.  80;  July  21,  1938,  p.  70. 

{71)   See  notes  24  and  29. 

{72)   See:    The  Iron  Age,  Aug.  11,  1938,  pp.  42,  64. 

(75)  See:  The  Iron  Age,  Oct.  13,  1938,  pp.  306,  308-309;  Oct.  20,  1938,  p.  66; 
Jan.  5,  1939,  pp.  110,  176. 

{74)  See  Table  1,  and  the  comment  in  The  Iron  Age,  Oct.  20,  1938,  p.  66,  and 
Jan.  5,  1939,  pp.  110,  176. 

(75)   See  Tables  5,  10,  14  and  16. 

{76)  See  Table  1,  and  the  comments  in  The  Iron  Age,  Jan.  5,  1939,  p.  221;  Jan. 
26,  1939,  pp.  74  and  76;  Feb.  2,  1939,  p.  96;  Feb.  23,  1939,  p.  76;  Mar.  2,  1939, 
pp.  70  and  84;   Mar.  23,  1939,  p.  82;  April  13,  1939,  p.  94. 

{77)  See,  for  example,  the  statements  in  The  Iron  Age,  Feb.  23,  1939,  p.  76; 
Mar.  2,  1939,  p.  70;  and  Mar.  30,  1939,  pp.  46-48. 

{78)  See  The  Iron  Age,  April  13,  1939,  p.  94;  April  27,  1939,  p.  88;  and  May 
4,  1939,  p.  98. 

{79)  See  the  discussion  in  The  Iron  Age,  May  11,  1939,  pp.  96  and  98;  May  18, 
1939,  pp.  124  and  126-127;  May  25,  1939,  pp.  61-62;  and  June  15,  1939,  pp.  69 
et  seq. 

{80)   See  Table  1,  and  Tfie  Iron  Age,  issues  from  June  to  August,  1939. 


Exhibit  No.  1413 

AN  ANjClYSIS  OF  THE  DEMAND  FOR  STEEL  IN  THE  AUTOMOBILE 
INDUSTRY 

This  is  an  analysis  prepared  by  the  Special  Economic  Research  Section  of  United 
States  Steel  Corporation,  composed  of  Messrs.  Edward  T.  Dickinson,  Jr.,  Ernest 
M.  Doblin,  H.  Gregg  Lewis,  Jacob  L.  Mosak,  Mandal  R.  Segal,  Dwight  B.  Yntema 
and  Miss  Marion  W.  Worthing.  The  work  of  this  group  was  under  the  supervision 
of  Theodore  O.  Yntema,  Professor  of  Statistics,  University  of  Chicago.  This 
analysis  was  written  by  Jacob  L.  Mosak  and  has  had  the  benefit  of  suggestions 
from  other  members  of  the  staff.    It  is  issued  by  United  States  Steel  Corporation 

November  1,  1939. 

contents 

I.  Purpose. 
II.  Summary  of  the  Findings. 

III.  The  Automobile  Industry. 

IV.  Steel  Consumption. 

V.  The  Demand  for  Automobiles: 

A.  Major  J'actors  Aflectins  the  Year  to  Year  Changes  in  Sales  of  New  Automobiles 

(1)  Consumer  Income. 

(2)  Potential  New  Owners  and  the  Maximum  Ownership  Level. 

(3)  Replacement  Demand. 

(4)  The  Price  of  Automobiles. 

B.  Secondary  Factors  .\ffectiiig  Retail  Sales 

(1)  Used  Car  Allowances. 

(2)  Financing  Terms. 

(3)  Operating  Costs. 

(4)  Dealers'  Used  Car  Stocks. 

VI.  The  Relation  of  Steel  Prices  to  the  Demand  for  Automotive  Steel. 

I.  Purpose 

The  purpose  of  this  study  is  to  review  ttie  factors  which  determine  the  de- 
mand for  steel  as 'a  raw  material  in  the  automobile  industry,  and  to  appraise 
particularly  the  relative  significance  of  the  price  of  steel  as  jne  of  these  factors. 


13982  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

II.  Summary  of  the  Findings 

The  quantity  of  steel  consumed  as  a  raw  material  by  the  automobile  manu- 
facturing industry  depends  directly  upon  (1)  the  number  of  cars  produced;  (2) 
the  quantity  of  steel  used  per  car;  and  (3)  the  production  of  replacement  parts 
and  related  equipment.  The  price  of  automotive  steel  can  afifect  the  quantity 
sold  only  by  influencing  one  or  more  of  these  three  factors. 

The  demand  for  automobiles  has  recently  been  the  subject  of  an  exhaustive 
study  by  C.  F.  Roos  and  Victor  von  Szeliski.i  They  found  that  the  number  of 
new  passenger  cars  sold  in  any  year  was  dependent  on  (1)  national  income;  (2) 
the  number  of  cars  in  operation;  (3)  the  age  distribution  of  cars  in  operation; 
(4)  the  scrapping  rate;  (5)  the  price;  and  (6)  other  factors  including  used  car 
allowances,  financing  terms,  operating  costs  and  dealers'  used  car  stocks.  After 
making  proper  allowance  for  the  influence  of  national  income,  number  of  cars  in 
operation,  age  distribution  and  scrapping  rate,  they  concluded  that  the  elasticity 
of  demand  for  new  passenger  cars  was  approximately  1.5;  or  in  other  words,  that 
a  1%  reduction  in  the  price  of  cars  would  cause  a  1.5%  increase  in  the  number  of 
cars  sold. 

A  change  in  the  price  of  steel  could  affect  the  number  of  automobiles  sold  only 
if  it  were  passed  on  to  the  ultimate  consumer  as  a  reduction  in  the  price  of  cars. 
The  cost  of  steel  in  a  car  is,  however,  only  approximately  13%  of  the  f.  o.  b.  price, 
or  approximately  lO%  of  the  delivered  price  of  the  car.  A  reduction  of  10%  in 
the  price  of  automotive  steel  would  therefore  permit  a  reduction  of  only  1%  in 
the  delivered  price  of  the  car  if  it  were  passed  on  entirely  to  the  consumer.  Since 
this  1%  reduction  in  automobile  prices  would  give  rise  to  only  a  1.5%  increase 
in  the  number  of  cars  sold,  it  follows  that  a  10%  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel 
would  give  rise  to  an  increased  consumption  of  steel  of  but  1.5%  through  its  eflFect 
on  the  number  of  cars  sold.  Thus  changes  in  the  price  of  steel  are  far  from  effec- 
tive in  raising  the  consumption  of  steel  through  increasing  the  volume  of  car 
sales. 

From  the  evidence  available,  the  price  of  steel  appears  to  have  an  even  less 
significant  effect  on  the  quantity  of  steel  used  per  car.  The  increased  use  of 
steel  per  car  over  the  past  fifteen  years  is  mainly  attributable  to  the  increased 
popularity  of  enclosed  models  and  heavier  cars,  and  intense  competition  among 
motor  companies  in  the  improvement  of  their  product.  The  conclusion  that  the 
price  of  steel  is  a  minor  influence  in  the  quantity  of  steel  consumed  per  car  is 
supported  by  the  absence  of  a  relationship  between  the  weight  of  passenger  cars 
and  the  price  of  steel  after  the  series  have  been  adjusted  for  secular  trends. 

Replacement  parts  and  accessories  have  a  value  only  about  one-seventh  as 
great  as  new  cars  produced.  It  seems  reasonable  to  conclude  that  the  elasticity 
of  demand  for  these  products  is  not  greatly  different  from  the  elasticity  of  de- 
mand for  new  cars.  But  even  if  p>arts  and  accessories  had  an  appreciably  higher 
elasticity  of  demand,  because  of  their  relatively  small  value  they  could  not  have 
much  effect  on  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  all  automotive  steel. 

The  total  effect  of  a  reduction  in  price  upon  the  consumption  of  steel  by  the 
automobile  industry,  through  increase  in  the  volume  of  car  production,  increase 
in  the  use  of  steel  per  car,  and  increase  in  the  production  of  replacement  parts 
and  accessories,  is  therefore  relatively  slight.  Combining  these  elements,  the 
elasticity  of  demand  for  automobile  steel  is  probably  not  in  excess  of  .2  or  .3. 
In  other  words,  a  10%  reduction  in  the  price  of  such  steel  could  not  increase  the 
consumption  of  steel  in  the  motor  vehicle  industry  by  more  than  2  or  3%. 

The  price  of  steel  is  therefore  a  minor  factor  in  determining  the  quantity  of  steel 
consumed  as  a  raw  material  in  the  automobile  industry. 

III.  The  Automobile  Industry 

A  brief  review  of  the  growth  of  the  automobile  industry  to  its  present-day 
position  is  ttesic  to  an  understanding  of  the  nature  of  the  demand  for  automobiles 
and  of  the  derived  demand  for  steel.  From  a  stage  of  infancy  in  1900  when  pro- 
duction amounted  to  only  4,000  vehicles,  the  manufacture  of  automobiles  rapidly 
matured  into  an  industry  of  first  importance  with  a  production  of  4  million  ve- 
hicles in  1923.  Between  1923  and  1929  production  averaged  about  4.4  million 
vehicles  annually,  of  which  more  than  85%  were  passenger  cars.  During  the 
same  period  the  dollar  volume  of  production  averaged  nearly  3  billions  annually, 
of  which  about  2.5  billions  represented  passenger  car  production.  In  the  recent 
peak  year,  1"  T7,  production  stood  at  5  million  motor  vehicles  having  a  whole- 
sale value  of  2,970  million  dollars.     Of  this  amount  about  80%  represented  pas- 

'  C.  F.  Roos  and  Victor  von  SzeliskI  "Factors  Oovernlng  Changes  iu  Domestic  Automobile  Demand", 
The  Dynamics  of  AtUormbUit  Demand,  General  Motors  Corporation,  N.  Y.,  1939. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13983 


senger  cars.^  In  the  census  year  1935  the  industry  gave  employment  to  164,000 
people  and  had  a  total  wage  bill  of  217  million  dollars.^ 

Complementary  to  the  motor  vehicle  industry  is  the  important  motor  vehicle 
bodies  and  parts  industry.  In  1935  this  industry  employed  60%  more  wage 
earners  and  had  a  50%  larger  wage  bill  than  did  the  motor  vehicle  manufacturing 
industry  proper.  If  the  two  industries  are  added  together  the  total  number  of 
employees  in  the  automotive  industry  in  1935  was  425,000  and  the  total  wage 
bill  was  545  miUion  dollars.^ 

However  the  dollar  volume  of  output  in  the  two  industries  cannot  be  added 
together,  since  that  would  involve  duplication.  It  has  been  estimated  that 
between  75  and  80%  of  the  production  of  motor  bodies  and  parts  ordinarily 
represents  original  equipment  entering  into  the  production  of  new  cars.  If  this 
portion  of  output  is  subtracted  from  the  total  it  appears  that  the  dollar  output  of 

Chart  1 


PRODUCTION  OF  AUTOMOBILES  AND  OF  PARTS  AND  ACCESSORIES, 
AND  TOTAL  NUMBER  OF  CARS  REGISTERED  IN  UNITED  STATES 


140 

1926 

=  100 

120 

REGISTRATIONS 

k. 

100 

^,^^ 

n^ 

,^ 

/ 

^ 

\'*"' 

'"y 

^-^ 

\ 

80 

> 

r 

V 

/ 

\ 

1 

// 

Y'* 

.PARTS  AND  ACCESSORIES 

60 

/^ 

f 

\ 

-\™o    -       - 

UCIION 

1 

A 

^ 

NJ  ^ 

^ 

40 

Z' 

t 

UTOMC 

BIcN 

r 

KUDUC 

TICN 

\, 

20 

^ 

,0-^ 

0 

60       X 

UJ 

o 

z 
40       - 

20 


:  Rae^'ch  and  Auto^ob-le  Manijf»r(u'''>g  Aaocai^n 


replacement  parts  at  producers'  prices  averaged  only  287  million  dollars  in  the 
census  years,  1923,  1925,  1927  and  1929.  If  in  addition  there  are  added  certain 
other  accessories  such  as  skid  chains,  stamped  automotive  parts  and  storage 
batteries,  the  total  production  at  producers'  prices  of  replacement  parts  and  ac- 
cessories averaged  407  million  dollars.^ 

It  has  been  estimated  that  in  1938  the  total  employment  offered  directly  and 
indirectly  in  motor  vehicle  bodies  and  parts,  tires  and  petroleum  refining  plants, 
sales  and  servicing,  road  building,  truck  and  bus  driving,  in  the  raw  material 
supply  industries  and  in  automobile  insurance  and  finance  companies  was  well 
over  6  million  persons."  This  is  about  14%  of  the  total  gainfully  employed  in  the 
United  States.  It  has  been  further  estimated  that  approximately  14  billion  dollars 
of  new  investment  went  into  the  furnishing  of  motor  transport  directly  and  in- 
directly in  the  period  1923  to  1929.'     This  is  about  equal  to  the  amount  that  was 

>  statistical  Abstract  of  the  United  Slates,  193R,  page  370. 

»  United  States  Department  of  Commerce,  Census  of  Manujactures,  1935,  page]29. 

*  Ibid. 

'  S.  Kuznets,  Commodity  Flow  and  Capital  Formation,  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research,  New  York, 
1938,  pages  66  and  88. 

•  Automobile  Facts  and  Figures,  Automobile  Manufacturers  Association,  1938,  page  47. 

'  Wendell  D.  Hance,  "The  Role  of  the  Automobile  Industry",  paper  presented  before  the  American  Eco- 
nomic Association,  December  28, 1938,  typescript,  pages  3-5.  See  also.  Automobile  Facts  and  Fitures,  Auto- 
mobile Manufacturers  Association,  1938,  page  51. 


13984 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


invested  during  the  same  period  in  railroads,  electric  power  and  telephone  com- 
panies combined. 5 

Like  other  durable  goods  industries,  however,  the  automotive  industry  has 
not  experienced  uninterrupted  gro\vth  but  has  been  subject  to  great  fluctuations  in 
production  and  employment.  This  is  shown  by  Chart  1  and  by  the  figures  on 
production,  employment,  and  payrolls  for  selected  years  given  in  Table  1 : 

As  is  to  be  expected,  the  fluctuations  in  the  consumers'  stocks  of  automobiles, 
as  evidenced  by  automobile  registrations,  are  much  smaller  in  amplitude  than  the 
fluctuations  in  production  (Chart  1).  This  follows  directly  from  the  fact  that 
the  automobile  is  a  durable  good.  Once  bought,  it  yields  services  over  a  period  of 
five  to  fifteen  years,  and  no  further  purchases  are  necessary,  except  for  replacement. 


Table  1. 


-Production,  Employment  and  Payrolls  in  the  Motor  Vehicle  Industry  for 
Selected  Years 


Year 

Produc- 
tion (mil- 
lions of 
cars) 

Bureau  of 
Labor  Sta- 
tistics In- 
dex of  Em- 
ployment, 
1923-5  =  100 
(monthly 
average) 

Bureau  of 
Labor  Sta- 
tistics In- 
dex of  Pay- 
rolls, 1923- 

5=100 
(monthly 
average) 

1921...                    .                                    ..... 

1.7 
5.6 
1.4 
5.0 

52.9 
111.3 

60.5 
128.3 

1929    .  . 

1932 

1937.. 

Sources:  Statistical  Abstract  of  the  United  States,  1938,  p.  370. 
ment,  pp.  32  and  41,  and  November,  1938.  pp.  14,  18. 


Survey  of  Current  Business,  1938  Supple- 


Replacement  purchases,  however,  can  be  postponed,  since  the  old  car  can  almost 
always  be  made  to  serve  another  year  if  economic  conditions  are  adverse.  This 
difference  in  fluctuation  is  clearly  seen'  by  comparing  the  figures  in  Table  2  on 
total  number  of  cars  registered  and  on  gasoline  consumption  with  those  shown 
above  on  production  and  employment  in  Table  1. 

Table  2. — Total  Number  of  Car§  Registered  and  Gasoline  Consumption  for  Selected 

Years 


Total  Num- 
ber of  Cars 
Registered 
(millions) 


Gasoline 
Consump- 
tion (mil- 
lion barrels) 


1921. 
1929.' 
1932. 


10.5 
26.5 
24.1 
29.7 


31.0 
31.2 
13.2 


Sources:  Automobile  Manufacturers  Association,  Automobile  Facts  and  Figures,  1938,  pp.  15  and  16,  and 
1929,  p.  14;  Survey  of  Current  Business,  1938  Supplement,  p.  121. 

Since  most  of  the  production  of  motor  bodies  and  parts  represents  original 
equipment  entering  into  the  production  of  new  cars,  it  is  natural  that  the  two 
series  should  have  similar  fluctuations,  as  shown  in  Table  3. 

Table  3. —  Value  of  product   in   the   aulomohile  industry  for   selected   years 
[Millions  of  dollars] 


Year 

Motor 
Vehicles 

Bodies  and 
Parts 

1929     . 

$3, 710 
1.568 
1,097 
2,391 

$1.  551 

1931...                                                                                                                       .  .  .. 

945 

1933 .                                  .               

756 

1935 ■. 

1,551 

Source:  Census  of  Manufactures,  1935,  pp.  1180  and  1156. 


'  Charts  and  Tables  for  Use  in  Hearings  on  Savings  and  Inreslment  before  the  Temporary  National  Economic 
Committee  May  16  to  iG,  1939,  Investment  Banking  Section,  Securities  Exchange  Commission.  Supplementary 
Table  I-a,  "Plant  and  Equipment  Expenditures",  introduced  by  Lauchlin  Currie,  M&i'  13,  1939. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13985 


It  appears,  however,  that  even  if  that  portion  of  the  production  of  all  accessories 
and  parts  which  is  used  for  replacement  purposes  is  segregated,  the  fluctuations 
in  this  segregated  series  still  conform  to  the  changes  in  automobile  production 
rather  than  to  those  in  the  total  number  of  cars  registered.'  This  indicates  that 
the  factors  affecting  the  demand  for  replacement  parts  are  roughly  the  same  as 
those  affecting  the  demand  for  automobiles. 

IV.  Steel  Consumption 

The  automotive  industry  has  been  the  largest  single  consumer  of  steel  for  five 
of  the  last  six  years,  taking  between  one-quarter  and  one-sixth  of  the  total  finished 
steel  output.  For  the  period  1923-1938  it  consumed  on  the  average  almost  5 
million  tons  of  steel  per  year.'"  About  125  different  kinds  of  steel  are  used  in  the 
modern  automobile.  Chief  among  these  are  sheets.  The  automobile  industry 
in  1937  took  about  45%  of  total  production  of  sheets,  and  in  addition  it  used 

Chart  2 


AUTOMOBILE  STEEL  CONSUMPTION  AND  AUTOMOBILE  PRODUCTION 

IN   UNITED  STATES 

CO 

Z           c 

O          = 

i 

8 
7 
6 

4       d 

■s. 

2 

1 
0 

; 

1 

V^CONSUMPirON 
A  (GROSS  IONS) 

/ 

y 

/" 

\ 

1 

/ 

/ 

\ 

J 

\ 

> 

/ 

\ 

A 

y 

^^ 

u 

kJ 

\ 

/ 

s\ 

/ 

y 

./ 

V 

( 

\ 

\ 

/ 

/ 

\;/ 

PRODUCT 

ON 

iilllllllliillllii 

about  55%  of  the  total  production  of  strip  and  45%  of  the  total  production  of 
bars.'i 

Large  quantities  of  steel  are  bought  annually  for  the  production  of  automobile 
accessories  and  parts  for  replacement.  As  has  already  been  noted,  the  annual 
production  of  these  parts  amounts  to  about  one-seventh  of  the  value  of  passenger 
cars  produced.  In  addition,  steel  is  bought  for  the  production  of  tools  and  dies, 
for  repairs  and  maintenance  and  for  capital  investment  in  plant  and  equipment 
of  the  automobile  industry. '^ 

The  latest  available  estimates  of  automotive  steel  consumption  show  that  the 
steel  shipments  to  the  automotive  industry  have  fluctuated  in  fairly  close  con- 
formity with  automobile  production.  From  Chart  2  it  appears  that  in  every 
year  1923-1938,  except  in  1929,  the  two  series  moved  in  the  same  direction, 
although,  it  should  be  noted,  the  changes  were  not  proportional  to  each  other.'^ 


•  See  Table  8  in  the  Appendix. 

'«  See  Table  9  in  the  Appendix. 

"  Automobile  Facts  and  Figures,  1938,  page  47. 

■2  The  automobile  industry  is,  of  course,  also  responsible  for  a  great  deal  of  steel  consumption  in  the  build- 
ing of  highways,  bridges,  filfing  stations,  and  plant  and  equipment  in  the  petroleiun  and  rubber  tires  indus- 
tries.   This  indirect  steel  consumption  is  not  dealt  with  here. 

'3  See  Table  9  in  the  Appendix.  The  available  data  on  steel  consumption  by  the  automobile  industry 
are  not  entirely  satisfactory,  since  the  coverage  and  classification  of  steel  purchases  in  the  magazine  Steel 
differ  from  those  in  Iron  Age,  and  the  coverage  and  classification  differ  from  year  to  year  in  the  sarpe  maga- 
zine.   However,  for  the  purposes  for  which  the  data  are  used  here  these  limitations  are  not  prohibitive. 


13986  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

An  important  feature  of  automotive  steel  consumption  has  been  the  ever 
continuous  tendency  to  increase  the  use  of  steel  in  automobile  construction. '< 
The  increased  use  of  steel  has  resulted  from  the  larger  size  of  modern  cars,  the 
adoption  of  all-steel  tops  and  bodies  by  automobile  producers  and  the  trend 
toward  heavier  cars  and  enclosed  models.  From  1925  to  1930  the  percentage 
of  open  model  cars  decreased  from  30%  to  0.5%. '^  In  recent  years,  however,  this 
tendency  has  been  somewhat  offset  by  the  use  of  greater  glass  area  and  of  plastics. 
Experiments  are  now  being  conducted  to  determine  the  practicability  of  using 
plastics  even  for  automobile  bodies.  If  successful,  this  may  have  an  appreciable 
effect  on  automotive  steel  consumption. 

V.  The  Demand  for  Automobiles 

The  authoritative  study  of  the  nature  of  the  demand  for  automobiles  made  by 
Messrs.  Roos  and  von  Szeliski  *'  relates  to  retail  sales  of  passenger  cars  within 
the  United  States  for  the  years  1919-38,  and  does  not  include  commercial  cars 
and  trucks,  nor  exports  of  any  vehicles.  This,  however,  is  not  a  serious  limita- 
tion, for,  as  already  noted,  passenger-car  production  represents  about  80%  of 
total  motor  vehicle  production,  and  domestic  sales  of  passenger  cars  constitute 
about  75%  of  total  sales."  The  following  analysis  draws  heavUy  upon  this 
study. 

A.    MAJOR   FACTORS    AFFECTING    THE    YEAR   TO    YEAR    CHANGES    IN    SALES    OF    NEW 
AUTOMOBILES 

As  with  all  durable  goods,  the  demand  for  new  automobiles  is  derived  from 
the  demand  for  services  which  they  yield.  Since  the  automobile  yields  trans- 
portation services  for  a  period  from  five  to  fifteen  years,  the  demand  for  these 
services  may  be  satisfied  by  running  the  old  cars  another  year  or  by  buying  used 
cars  instead  of  new  cars.  Thus  the  consumption  of  automobile  services  is  dis- 
associated from  the  purchases  of  new  cars,  and,  as  is  to  be  expected,  the  former 
is  far  more  stable  than  the  latter.  This  is  illustrated  in  Chart  1  and  in  Table  8 
in  the  Appendix,  in  which  automobile  production  is  contrasted  with  registrations. 
The  number  of  cars  in  use  held  up  relatively  well  even  in  the  trough  of  the  de- 
pression, while  the  sale  of  new  cars  suffered  a  great  decline. 

(1)  Consumer  Income. — The  level  of  consumer  income  is,  of  course,  a  major 
factor  in  determining  the  number  of  new  car  sales.  When  the  level  of  income 
is  high,  sales  will  be  high;  conversely,  when  national  income  is  low,  car  sales 
will  be  low.  This  is  illustrated  in  Table  4  and  in  Chart  3,  which  relate  new' car 
sales  to  consumer  disposable  income  (Table  4,  Columns  2  and  3,  and  Chart  3). 

"<  See  Table  7. 

"  Steel  Facta,  American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute,  December,  1930,  No.  16,  page  3. 

!•  Op.,  cit.  supra, 

"  S  L.  Horner,  "Statement  of  the  Problem,"  The  Dynamics  of  Automobile  Demand,  page  7. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13987 


Table  4. 


-Retail  Passenger   Car  Sales,   Disposable  Income,   Minimum   Cost  of 
Living  and  Supernumerary  Income,  1919-1938 


Year 

(1) 

Retail  Pas- 
senger Car 

Sales ' 
(thousand 

units) 

(2) 

Disposable 
Income  2 
(billion 
dollars) 

(3) 

Necessi- 
tous Liv- 
ing Costs  > 
(billion 
doUars) 

(4) 

Super- 
numerary 
Income  ♦ 
(bUlion 
dollars) 

(6) 

1919. 

1,591 
1,657 
1,471 
2,088 
3,351 
3,172 
3,252 
3,495 
2,705 

2]  652 
1,903 
1,096 
1,526 
1,928 
»  2,  531 

»  i  749 
«  1, 850 

$61.38 
66.29 
53.60 
56.45 
64.98 
66.02 
69.46 
72.94 
72.53 
74.92 
78.50 
71.21 
60.29 
46.67 
45.23 
52.38 
55.65 
63.06 
68.97 
64.20 

$21.92 
25.44 
22.22 
21.38 
22.30 
22.98 
23.86 
24.18 
24.02 
24.08 
24.30 
23.68 
21.52 
19.42 
18.82 
20.10 
20.90 
21.66 
22.76 
22.66 

$39.46 

1920 

40  85 

1921 

31.38 

1922 

35.07 

1924        -           .-      -  .             

43.04 

45.60 

1926 -.. 

48.76 

1927 

48.51 

1928 

50  84 

1929 

54.20 

1930 

47.63 

1931 

38.77 

27.25 

1933 — 

1934.. 1 

32.28 

1935 

34  65 

1936 

41  40 

1937 

46.21 

Source:  Data  used  by  Roos  and  von  Szeliski  in  The  Dynamics  0}  Automobile  Demand. 

1  For  1919-1925  the  data  represent  factory  production,  less  exports  and  foreign  assemblies,  less  assumed 
changes  in  dealers'  stocks;  for  1926-1929  the  data  are  estimated  by  General  Motors  from  retail  sales  of  General 
Motors  passenger  cars  and  new  car  registrations  of  other  passenger  cars;  for  1930-1938  the  data  are  estimates 
of  the  Automobile  Manufacturers  Association. 

>  Figures  for  1929-1938  are  Department  of  Commerce  income  payments  series,  plus  eatrepreneurial  sav- 
ings, less  Federal  income,  gift,  estate  and  inheritance  taxes;  figures  for  1919-1928  are  a  backward  extension 
of  1929-1938  figures,  on  basis  of  data  provided  In  Kuznets'  National  Income  and  Capital  Forviation,  1919- 
1935,  less  Federal  and  direct  taxes. 

'  Estimated  at  $200  per  capita  for  1923  and  varying  with  the  National  Industrial  Conference  Board  Index 
of  the  Cost  of  Living  for  other  years. 

'  Equals  column  (3)  minus  column  (4). 

»  Model  year  (12  months)  ending  in  October. 

A  somewhat  more  refined  analysis  is  possible  if  consumer  income  is  adjusted 
by  deducting  necessitous  expenditure.  Before  distributing  his  income  among 
different  commodities  or  between  savings  and  spending,  the  individual  consumer 
must  first  allocate  a  portion  to  meet  his  necessary  living  costs.  Messrs.  Roos 
and  von  SzeHski  estimate  the  t;ubsistence  or  necessitous  living  cost  to  have  been 
$200  per  capita  for  1923  and  to  have  varied  in  other  years  with  the  National 
Industrial  Cfonference  Board  index  of  the  cost  of  living. 


13988 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Deducting  these  costs  from  disposable  consumer  income,  they  obtain  estimates 
of  "supernumerary  income"  which  is  available  for  expenditures  on  automobiles 
and  other  goods  (Table  4,  Column  5). 

It  will  be  observed  from  Charts  3  and  4  that  for  a  given  amount  oJ  disposable 
or  supernumerary  income  the  sales  of  automobiles  are  characteristically  much 
higher  when  income  is  rising  than  when  it  is  falling.  The  reason  for  this  has  long 
been  known.  The  demand  for  automobiles,  as  for  most  durable  goods,  depends 
not  only  on  the  level  of  income  but  on  psychological  factors  such  as  the  state  of 
confidence.  Declining  business  activity  and  decreasing  income  give  rise  to  un- 
certainty and  to  fears  that  income  will  decline  still  further.  As  a  result,  even 
relatively  high  levels  of  income  may  be  associated  with  a  low  volume  of  sales. 
Conversely,  increasing  business  activity  and  income  lead  to  increased  confidence, 
and  to  the  allocation  of  an  increasing  proportion  of  present  and  future  income  to 
automobile  purchases. 

The  rate  of  change  of  the  national  income  may  be  taken  as  an  approximate 
index  of  this  psychological  factor.     If  the  rate  of  change,  as  well  as  the  level  of 

Chart  3 


2,500 


1,000 

500 

0 


RELATION  OF  PASSENGER  CAR  SALES  TO 
DISPOSABLE  INCOME 

IN  UNITED  STATES 


l*» 

19J7. 

'?* 

I9». 

•»"     .9«. 
•I924 

IJSt 

-"» 

>»?   .1927 

.1922 

,,33 

.,-34 

.1919 

.1920 

\ 

.193? 

loz. 

c 

50  5b  60  65  70 

BILLIONS  OF  DOLLARS  OF  DISPOSABLE  INCOME 


Souaw:   "ThtOrnamaal 


national  income,  is  taken  into  account,  the  relationship  to  sales  is  seen  to  be 
much  closer  than  appears  from  the  use  of  national  income  alone. '*  Although  the 
introduction  of  the  rate  of  change  of  the  national  income  as  a  factor  in  the  analysis 
does  help  to  explain  variations  in  the  demand  for  automobiles,  it  is  not  an 
entirely  satisfactory  measure  of  consumer  confidence,  since  other  phenomena 
have  ajjpreciable  infiuence  on  the  psychological  reactions  of  automobile  buyers. 
A  given  rate  of  change  may  have  little  effect  on  sales  at  one  time  and  a  great 
effect  at  another.  The  rate  of  change  in  income  is,  therefore,  at  best  only  an 
approximate  index  of  these  psychological  factors. 

(2)  Potential  New  Oivners  and  the  Maximum  Ownership  Level. — The  concept  of 
Messrs.  Koos  and  von  Szeliski  of  potential  new  ownership  and  of  the  maximum 
ownership  level  is  an  important  contril)ution  to  the  analysis  of  the  demand  for 
automobiles,  since  it  not  only  explains  the  relationship  between  income  and  auto- 
mobile sales  but  also  presents  a  logical  analysis  of  the  major  forces  determining 
the  sales  of  automobiles. 

Briefly  summarized,  their  explanation  is  as  follows: 

(a)  At  any  given  time  under  given  economic  conditions  there  is  a  maximum 
number  of  cars  that  will  be  kc[)t  in  operation.     In  the  long  run,  changes  in  this 

'»  S.  L.  norncr,  op.  cil.  supra.  . 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13989 


maximum  ownership  level  depend,  of  course,  on  the  growth  of  population,  on  the 
development  of  highways,  and  on  technical  progress.  From  year  to  year,  how- 
ever, the  level  changes  in  response  to  the  economic  status  of  consumers,  and  to 
other  factors  such  as  price  and  durability  of  the  car. 

(b)  The  number  of  potential  new  owners  is  equal  to  the  difference  between  the 
maximum  ownership  level  and  the  existing  consumers'  stock  of  cars. 

(c)  The  number  of  new  owner  sales  is  proportional  to  the  number  of  potential 
new  owners,  and  to  factors  dependent  on  income,  price,  trade-in  allowance, 
volume  of  installment  credit,  and  similar  factors. 

(d)  Thus  the  demand  factors  are  made  to  enter  twice  in  the  analysis  of  auto- 
mobile sales,  first  in  determining  th  maximum  ownership  level  under  any  given 
set  of  economic  conditions,  and  secoi  d  in  determining  the  nature  of  the  reaction 
of  sales  to  changes  in  the  number  of  i  otential  new  owners. 

(e)  By  means  of  these  concepts,  the  relationship  between  income  and  auto- 
mobile sales  is  explained.  Assuming  other  factors  to  remain  constant,  the  maxi- 
mum ownership  level  at  any  given  time  depends  on  the  level  of  income  at  that 

Chart  4 


2.500 
2,000 
1.500 
1,000 
500 
0 


RELATION  OF  PASSENGER  CAR  SALES  TO 
SUPERNUMERARY  INCOME 

IN  UNITED  STATES 


1929. 

.1937 

■i^;"" 

..«.-^ 

.!«• 

1935. 

.930.  r„, 

1922 

.1933 

■13. 

1919. 

•  1938 
•1920 

.1932 

Jni 

3,500 


3.000 

o 

i^ 

2,500 

o 

2,000 

o 

z 
< 

1,500 
1,000 

3 
O 

500 

0 

25  30  35  40  45  50  55 

BILLIONS  OF  DOLLARS  OF  SUPERNUMERARY  INCOME 


"  Tht  Oywno  cl  AuOmMe  Dr^t.-'d  " 


time,  but  the  stock  of  cars  in  operation  depends  on  previous  income.  The  num- 
ber of  potential  new  owners  is  the  difference  between  the  maximum  ownership 
level  and  the  stock  of  cars  in  operation  and  depends  therefore  on  the  difference 
between  this  year's  and  previous  years'  income.  Thus,  while  it  is  the  change  in 
income  from  Yoxst  levels  which  determines  the  number  of  potential  owners,  it  is 
the  current  level  of  income  which  determines  the  relation  between  the  volume  of 
sales  and  the  number  of  potential  new  owners. 

(f)  The  maximum  ownership  level  is  a  potent  force  in  determining  the  volume 
of  new  car  sales.  A  sudden  increase  in  income  may  increase  the  maximum  owner- 
ship level  to  a  figure  far  above  the  number  of  cars  in  operation  and  thus  lead  to 
a  very  large  increase  in  car  sales.  This  is  undoubtedly  what  happened  in  1937. 
On  the  other  hand  a  sudden  decline  in  income  may  decrease  the  maximum  owner- 
ship level  to  a  figure  below  the  number  of  cars  in  operation.  In  that  case  there 
will  be  an  actual  liquidation  of  part  of  the  stock  of  cars  in  operation.  This  is 
what  happened  during  the  depression  years  1930-32. 

(3)  Replacement  Demand. — Messrs.  Roos  and  von  Szeliski's  theory  with  respect 
to  replacement  demand  is  as  follows: 

(a)  Not  only  do  consumers  adjust  the  number  of  cars  in  operation  towards  the 
maximum  ownership  level,  but  they  also  adjust  the  quality  of  the  cars  in  operation 
towards  some  optimum  level  by  means  of  replacement. 


13990 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


(b)  Replacement  demand  depends  on  the  pressure  for  replacement,  and  on  such 
economic  factors  as  price,  income  and  trade-in  allowances. 

(c)  The  age  distribution  of  the  cars  in  operation  combined  with  experience 
tables  for  scrapping  furnishes  a  measure  of  the  pressure  for  replaceinent.  The 
studies  of  car  survival  which  have  been  made  since  1926  show  that  car  life  during 
the  last  fifteen  to  twenty  years  has  slowly  increased.  Griffin's  study  of  1926  shows 
50%  of  the  cars  surviving  about  seven  years,  whereas  the  most  recent  study  based 
on  1933-37  registrations  shows  50%  surviving  about  nine  years.  From  these 
frtudies  may  be  computed  the  percentage  of  an  original  group  of  cars  that  is 
scrapped  after  the  first,  second,  third,  etc.,  year  of  service.  By  application  of 
these  percentages  to  the  figures  giving  the  age  distribution  of  the  cars  in  operation 
in  any  year  a  measure  of  the  replacement  pressure  during  that  year  is  obtained. 
This  index  represents  the  theoretical  scrapping  rate.'' 

(d)  Theoretical  scrapping,  however,  merely  indicates  normal  replacement  pres- 
sure. It  is  not  equal  to  actual  replacement  since  this  varies  with  economic  cir- 
cumstances. In  times  of  prosperity  people  scrap  more  cars  than  is  indicated  by 
theoretical  scrapping.  The  converse  is  true  in  periods  of  depression.  Thus  in 
1929  actual  scrapping  was  about  one-third  higher  than  theoretical  scrapping, 
whereas  in  1933  it  was  about  60%  lower  than  the  theoretical  rate.''"  Replacement 
sales  therefore  depend  not  only  on  theoretical  scrapping  but  on  income  and  price 
and  other  economic  factors. 

(4)  The  Pi  ice  of  Automobiles. — The  almost  continuous  reduction  (until  1933)  of 
car  prices  (Appendix  Table  12)  undoubtedly  contributed  significantly  to  the 
great  development  of  the  automobile  industry.  The  effect  which  price  changes 
have  on  year  to  year  changes  in  sales  is,  however,  a  more  difficult  question. 

One  of  the  major  difficulties  encountered  is  the  fact  that  manufacturing  speci- 
fications change  so  frequently.  Since  price  changes  do  not  occur  separately  but 
in  conjunction  with  changes  in  car  models,  it  is  impossible  to  segregate  satis- 
factorily the  influence  of  price  changes  on  car  sales. 

A  second  difficulty  in  analyzing  the  effect  of  price  changes  is  the  fact  that  there 
have  not  been  suflBciently  wide  fluctuations  in  car  prices  to  warrant  very  reliable 
conclusions.  A  lonp-run  decline  in  car  prices  has  been  associated  with  a  long-run 
increase  in  sales.  But  since  year  to  year  changes  in  price  have  not  been  large, 
it  is  difficult  to  discover  what  effect  they  have  had  on  year  to  year  changes  in  gales. 

Another  major  problem  in  any  statistical  analysis  of  the  effects  of  changes  in 
car  prices  upon  volume  of  sales  is  the  construction  of  a  price  index.  Automobiles 
have  improved  so  rapidly  in  quality,  and  the  changes  in  design  and  construction 
have  been  so  frequent,  that  it  is  next  to  impossible  to  construct  a  satisfactory  price 
index.  The  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  index  of  wholesale  prices,  which  is  an 
average  of  prices  of  different  makes,  has  been  shown  to  be  seriously  in  error.'^ 
The  index  used  by  Roos  and  von  Szeliski  is  the  average  delivered  price  of  the 
lowest  priced  cars  freely  available  in  volume  (Ford,  Chevrolet,  and  Plymouth). 
Their  assumption  underlying  the  use  of  this  index  is  that  this  average  price  deter- 
mines the  number  of  cars  sold,  and  that  the  prices  of  other  cars  merely  determine 
the  distribution  of  sales  among  the  various  makes.'' 

Roos  and  von  Szeliski  conclude  that  price  has  not  been  a  very  important  factor 
in  determining  automobile  sales.  The  usual  measure  of  the  responsiveness  of 
quantity  sold  to  price  is  the  elasticity  of  demand,  or  the  ratio  of  the  percentage 
change  in  the  quantity  sold  to  the  percentage  change  in  price.  It  was  found  that 
this  elasticity  was  not  constant  but  varied  from  year  to  year  with  changes  in 
economic  conditions,  particularly  with  changes  in  income  and  in  the  maximum 
ownership  level. 

The  figures  below  give  the  statistical  estimates  on  the  elasticity  of  demand  for 
the  years  1919-1938: 

Table  5. — Elasticity  of  Demand  for  Automobiles  with  Respect  to  Price,  1919-19S8 


1919-. 

1.03 

1926 

1.26 

1933 

1.30 

1920._ 

1.04 

1927. 

1.33 

1934 

1.34 

1921. _ 

1.04 

1928 

1.37 

1935 

1.34 

1922-. 

1.05 

1929 

1.41 

1936 

1.33 

1923... 

1.05 

1930 

1.51 

1937 

1.38 

1924... 

1.  15 

1931 

1.46 

1938 

1.53 

1925... 

1.22 

1932 

1.44 

Source: 

Roos  and  von  Szeliski,  2 

he  Dynamic)  of  Automobile  Demand 

p.  94. 

'•  See  Roos  and  von  Szeliski,  op.  cit.  supra,  pages  47-53. 
"  See  Roos  and  von  Szeliski,  op.  cit.  supra,  page  52,  chart  15. 

"  A.  T.  Court,  "Hedonic  Price  Indexes",  The  Dynamics  of  Automobile  Demand,  pages  99-103. 
'»  This  index  is  available  only  since  1920.    For  ttie  years  1919-25  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  Index  was 
used. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13991 

These  are  presented  as  the  best  estimates  of  the  elasticity  of  demand.  The 
authors  point  out  that  the  elasticity  may  be  anywhere  between  .65  and  2.5, 
and  that  1.5  is  probably  a  good  representative  figure.  It  will  be  noted  that 
there  has  been  a  long-run  tendency  for  the  elasticity  to  increase  except  in  periods 
of  depression. 

For  comparison,  there  are  given  below  their  findings  on  the  income  elasticity 
or  the  responsiveness  of  demand  to  changes  in  supernumerary  income. 

Table  6. — Elasticity  of  Demand  for  Automobiles  with  Rested,  to  Income,  1919- 

1938 


1919 

_.-.-.  1.55 

1926 

2.08 

1933 

2.19 

1920 

1.65 

1927 

2.20 

1934 

2.  19 

1921.._.  ... 

1.56 

1928 

2.25 

1935 

2.20 

1922... 

1.61 

1929 

2.39 

1936 

2.25 

1923 

......  1.69 

1930-. 

2.62 

1937 

2.40 

1924... • 

1.80 

1931 

2.57 

1938 

2.58 

1925 

1.94 

1932 

......  2.44 

Sonrce:  Roos  and  von  Szeliskl,  The  Dynamics  of  Automobile  Demand,  p.  89. 

Since  the  income  elasticity  is  considerably  higher  than  the  price  elasticity  it 
is  evident  that  the  influence  of  price  on  sales  is  not  suflSciently  powerful  to  over- 
come the  effect  of  the  wide  swings  in  income  during  the  business  cycle.  Even 
if  the  price  elasticity  were  equal  to  the  income  elasticity,  it  would  require  a 
50%  reduction  in  price  to  offset  a  50%  decline  in  income.  Since  cash  costs 
for  raw  materials,  tools,  wages,  salaries,  taxes,  and  other  out  of  pocket  expenses 
constitute  about  90%  of  the  wholesale  price  of  a  car  it  is  obvious  that  such 
reduction  in  price  unaccompanied  by  a  reduction  in  costs  would  be  disastrous.^* 

B.  SECONDART  FACTORS  AFFECTING  RETAIL  SALES 

The  factors  listed  above  account  for  all  but  a  small  part  of  the  annual  variation  in 
retail  sales  of  automobiles.  There  are,  howpver,  some  secondary  factors  which 
are  highly  correlated  with-  those  we  have  considered  and  whose  iflfleucnce  it  is 
therefore  diflBcult  to  segregate  from  the  rest.  In  certain  years  these  forces  may 
be  of  particular  importance  in  stimulating  or  discouraging  sales. 

(1)  Used  Car  Allowances. — The  used  car  allowance  is  one  such  factor.  Since 
the  net  cash  cost  to  the  buyer  of  a  new  car  is  the  difference  between  the  new 
car  price  and  the  used  car  allowance,  it  is  obvious  that  the  size  of  the  the  allow- 
ance must  affect  new  car  sales.  In  the  statistical  study  made  by  Roos  and  von 
Szeliski  it  was,  however,  impossible  to  measure  this  effect. 

(2)  Financing  Terms. — Financing  terms  have  become  progressively  easier. 
The  percentage  of  installment  contracts  running  more  than  12  months  rose 
from  14.5%  in  1928  to  68%  in  1937.  The  percentage  of  down  payments  that 
were  under  standard  terms  (33>i%  on  new  cars,  40%  on  used  cars)  rose  from 
6.1  %  to  23.3%  during  the  same  period.  Beginning  in  1935  the  easing  of  financing 
terms  was  particularly  marked.^*  This  undoubtedly  has  had  an  important 
effect  on  the  increased  volume  of  purchases  of  new  cars  since  1935. 

(3)  Operating  Costs. — Operating  costs  are  particularly  important  as  a  long-run 
trend  factor  determining  the  maximum  level  of  ownership.  The  better  the  quality 
of  the  car  and  the  lower  the  annual  operating  and  maintenance  costs,  the  greater 
is  the  number  of  cars  that  will  be  kept  in  operation. 

Operating  costs  were  not  included  as  a  separate  variable  in  the  statistical 
study.  The  variation  in  operating  costs  has,  however,  closely  paralleled  the  varia- 
tion in  automobile  prices,  and  it  is  difficult  therefore  to  separate  their  respective 
effects  on  the  volume  of  automobile  sales.  Roos  and  von  Szeliski  have  made 
estimates  of  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  automobiles  2«  when  the  effects  of  oper- 
ating costs  are  included  and  also  when  they  are  excluded.  It  is  the  latter  series 
which  has  been  used  in  the  section  on  prices  (Table  5). 

(4)  Dealers'  Used  Car  Stocks. — Dealers'  used  car  stocks  undoubtedly  have  im- 
portant effects  on  sales  of  new  cars  in  some  years.  When  used  car  stocks  are  large, 
dealers  tend  to  push  the  sales  of  used  cars  with  greater  vigor,  and  they  lower  their 
trade-in  allowances.  Both  of  these  have  a  depressing  effect  on  sales  of  new  cars. 
Unfortunately  no  data  are  available  on  the  number  and  value  of  used  cars  in 
dealer  hands,  and  it  is  difficult  to  get  any  statistical  evidence  on  this  point. 
However,  even  a  superficial  examination  of  the  automotive  journals  indicates  that 
this  is  at  times  a  major  problem. 

"  See  S.  M.  Dubrul,  "Significance  of  the  Findings",  Dynamics  of  Automobile  Demand,  pages  123-39. 
'*  Roos  and  von  Szeliski,  op.  cU.  supra,  page  68. 
"  Roos  and  von  Szeliski,  op.  cit  supra,  pages  92t  94. 


13992  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

VI.  The  Relation  of  Steel  Prices  to  the  Demand  for  Automotive  Steel 

Since  automotive  steel  is  purchased  primarily  as  a  raw  material  for  the  produc- 
tion of  cars,  consumption  of  steel  by  the  automotive  industry  bears  a  direct  relation 
to  production  of  cars.  This  is  illustrated  by  the  data  on  automobile  production 
and  steel  consumption  ^6  in  Chart  2.  In  almost  every  year  from  1923  to  1938  the 
two  series  moved  in  the  same  direction  and  had  approximately  the  same  relative 
magnitude  of  fluctuation.  For  the  period  as  a  whole,  however,  there  was  a  long- 
run  tendency  for  the  consumption  of  steel  to  increase  by  a  greater  percentage  than 
automobile  production.  This  is  shown  by  the  upward  trend  in  steel  consumption 
per  automobile  (Table  7). 

In  contrast  to  the  close  relationship  between  steel  consumption  and  automobile 
production,  there  is  little,  if  any,  relation  between  steel  consumption  and  steel  prices. 
This  is  illustrated  graphically  in  Chart  5,  in  which  both  the  composite  feteel  price 
and  the  simple  average  of  sheet  and  strip  prices  are  plotted."     The  consumption 

Chart  5 


z 
o 

1- 

u. 

o 

V) 

z 
o 

-1 

i 

AUTOMOBILE  §TEEL  CONSUMPTION  AND  STEEL  PRICES 

IN   UNITED  STATES 

9 
8 
7 
6 
5 
4 

3 
2 

1 

_    _ 

9 

8 

7 

6 

5       1 

4       1 

q: 
3       ^ 

</) 

'    1 

1 

^AUTOMOBILE  SI 

EEL 

^ 

■^ 

y 

■s. 

V 

^NSU 

<PIH 

/ 

f 

\ 

V 

/ 

sj 

t¥ 

roMO 

IHU 

\ 

1 

X 

•*«*» 

n 
***=, 

-=^ 

•-'^ 

as* 

i 

^ 



.— 

^ 

-. 

STE£ 

.  PRK 

f£ 

ktt, 

^iilllillliiiiiiis 

series  (Appendix  Table  9)  and  price  series  (Appendix  Table  10)  move  in  the  same 
direction  about  as  often  as  they  move  in  the  opposite  direction. 

This  conclusion  is  further  supported  by  Chart  6,  a  scatter  diagram  of  auto- 
motive steel  consumption  against  automotive  steel  prices.  In  this  chart,  per- 
centage changes  in  annual  consumption  and  annual  average  price  are  shown  in 
relation  to  each  other.  Since  the  scatter  diagram  fails  to  indicate  that  lower  steel 
prices  have  been  associated  historically  with  greater  quantities  of  steel  purchased 
and  vice  versa,  it  justifies  the  view  that  price  has  been  less  important  than  other 
influences  in  determining  the  consumption  of  automobile  steel. 

As  was  pointed  out  earlier  in  the  discussion,  the  quantity  of  steel  consumed  as  a 
raw  material  in  the  automobile  industry  depends  directly  upon  three  factors: 

(1)  The  number  of  cars  produced; 

(2)  The  quantity  of  steel  used  per  car; 

(3)  The  production  of  replacement  parts  and  accessories. 

A  change  in  the  price  of  steel  can,  consequently,  affect  the  consumption  of  steel 
only  as  (1)  it  leads  to  a  correspondin"g  change  in  the  price  of  automobiles  and  tlius 

2«  See  Note  13  regarding  limitations  of  data. 

2'  See  Table  10  in  the  .'vppondix  for  these  prices.  This  average  of  hot  and  cold  rolled  sheet  and  hot 
rolled  strip  prices  is  henceforth  referred  to  as  the  automotive  steel  price.  A  simple  average  of  the  prices  of  these 
steels  was  taken  because  (1)  they  are  the  most  important  kinds  of  steel  used  in  making  automobiles  and 
(2)  they  arc  used  in  about  e^ual  amounts  per  car. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


13993 


to  an  inverse  change  in  the  number  of  automobiles  sold,  or  (2)  it  induces  the 
manufacturers  of  automobiles  to  change  the  quantity  of  steel  used  per  car,  or 
(3)  it  causes  a  change  in  the  production  of  replacement  parts  and  accessories. 

Considering  first  the  influence  of  steel  prices  on  automobile  prices  and  produc- 
tion, we  find  it  impossible  to  determine  directly  from  an  examination  of  steel 
prices  whether  a  change  in  the  price  of  steel  used  by  the  automobile  industry  has 
had  any  direct  effect  on  the  price  of  automobiles.  (See  Chart  7  and  see  Table  12 
in  the  Appendix.)  The  statistics  show  merely  that  both  series  of  prices  moved 
in  a  long-run  downward  trend  until  1933,  and  thereafter  moved  horizontally  or 
upward.  It  will  be  observed  also  that  the  movements  in  these  price  series  were 
not  greatly  different  from  the  movements  of  a  broad  price  index  of  manufactured 
goods  during  the  same  period.  From  this  statistical  evidence  it  is  impossible  to 
infer  whether  changes  in  the  price  of  steel  did  or  did  not  cause  changes  in  automobile 
prices. 

It  is  possible,  however,  to  discover  the  extent  to  which  steel  prices  might  affect 
car  prices  by  an  analysis  of  the  cost  of  steel  in  an  automobile.     As  is  shown  in 

Chart  6 


o 

180 

S 

<^ 

160 

fe 

^ 

140 

2 

o 

1?0 

'n 

CO 

100 

RELATION  OF  AUTOMOBILE  STEEL  PRICE  TO 
AUTOMOBILE  STEEL  CONSUMPTION 


1933  • 

1925. 

.,., 

193S 

1926. 

.1936 

19.U. 

I937. 

1927. 

•  1929 

1931. 

.1924 
•1930 

-           .1,3. 

90  IQO  110  120 

AUTOMOBILE  STEEL  PRICE  IN  %  OF  PREVIOUS  YEAR 


130 


Table  11  in  the  Appendix,  the  cost  of  steel  used  in  the  manufacture  of  a  Chevrolet 
sedan  is  approximately  13%  of  the  F.  O.  B.  price  or  approximately  10%  of  the 
delivered  price  of  the  car.^^  A  reduction  of  10%  in  the  price  of  automotive  steel 
would  therefore  permit  a  reduction  of  only  1%  in  the  dehvered  price  of  the  car  if 
the  reduction  were  passed  on  entirely  to  the  consumer.  The  effect  of  changes  in 
car  prices  on  car  sales  has  been  studied  by  Roos  and  von  Szeliski,  and  their  esti- 
mates of  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  automobiles  appear  in  Table  5  of  this 
memorandum.  Their  figure  of  1.5  for  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  automobiles 
means  that  a  1%  change  in  the  price  of  automobiles  gives  rise  to  a  1.5%  change 
in  the  number  of  automobiles  sold.  Since  a  10%  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel, 
if  passed  on  entirely  to  the  buyer,  is  equivalent  to  only  a  1%  reduction  in  the  price 
of  the  car,  it  would  increase  the  volume  of  car  sales  and  therefore  the  consumption 
of  steel  by  only  1.5%.  Even  if  the  maximum  limit  of  2.5  estimated  by  Roos  and 
von  Szeliski  be  taken  as  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  automobiles,  the  effec  of  a 
10%  drop  in  the  price  of  steel,  if  passed  on  to  the  consumer,  would  be  to  increase 

«« In  heavier,  higher  priced  automobiles  the  quantity  of  steel  used  does  not  increase  proportionately  with 
price,  *nd  consequently  the  ratio  of  steel  co.'  t  to  retail  price  falls  below  10%. 


13994 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


car  sales  and  automotive  steel  consumption  by  only  2.5%."  It  is  evident,  there- 
fore, that  a  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel  is  not  an  effective  means  for  raising  steel 
consumption  through  increases  in  car  sales  and  car  production. 

The  effect  of  a  reduction  in  the  price  04'  steel  on  the  quantity  of  steel  used  per 
car  is,  so  far  as  can  be  determined,  practically  negligible.  During  the  past 
fifteen  years  a  number  of  factors  have  contributed  to  an  increased  use  of  steel 
per  car.     These  are: 

(1)  The  increased  popularity  of  enclosed  models  and  heavier  cars; 

(2)  Engineering  improvements  in  the  production  of  both  steel  and  auto- 
mobiles; 

Chaet  7 


PRICES  OF  AUTOMOBILE  STEEL, 
AUTOMOBILES  AND  MANUFACTURED  GOODS 

!N  UNITED- STATES 

4 

cr. 

<r>         2 

0 

1 

0 

100 
1      80 

1      ^° 

z 

40 
20 

\ 

30      2 

20   e 

10 
0 

\ 

^N 

PP 

AUT 

ICE 

OMO 
'ER 

BILE 
POU 

MD 

^ 

V 

V 

y 

;2; 

s: 

4 

> 

AUl 
PR 

OMOBILE 
CE  PER 

ST 

=ou 

EL 
40 

^ 

^ 

k 

192 

1 
6=  100 

100 

80      1 
60      Q 
40 
20 

"^ 

^ 

'n 

d 

s 

AUVOM 
PR! 

)BIL 

:e^ 

x 

^ 

^ 

^ 

MANUF 

^CTl 

RED 

GOC 

)0S 

. 

PR 

IVMOL 

CE 

) 

s 

^.,:    Aon  ^5^. 

iiiilissliisllil 

(3)  Intense  competition  among  motor  companies  pointed  toward  improve- 
ment of  their  product. 

There  is,  however,  no  logical  or  statistical  basis  for  inferring  that  the  price  of 
steel  has  been  a  significant  factor  in  causing  the  increased  use  of  steel  per  car. 
Unfortunately,  the  statistical  series  available  on  the  steel  consumption  per 
automobile  are  none  too  satisfactory.  Attempts  to  derive  such  a  series  from 
the  estimates  of  steel  consumption  by  the  automobile  industry  appearing  in  the 

"  It  might  appear  that  a  reduction  in  the  price  of  automobiles  made  possible  by  a  general  decrease  in  all 
cost  components  would  bo  an  effective  means  of  stimulating  automobile  purchases.  The  elasticity  figures 
here  quoted,  however,  do  not  apply  to  price  reductions  accompanied  by  a  general  deflation  in  the  prices  of 
the  cost  factors  throughout  the  economy.  The  effects  of  general  deflation  in  prices  and  costs  are  too  compli- 
cated and  complex  to  explore  here. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13995 

trade  magazines,  Iron  Age  and  Steel,  led  to  the  conclusion  that  these  estimates 
were  too  inaccurate  for  this  purpose.'"  Resort  was  had,  therefore,  to  estimates  of 
the  average  dry  shipping  weight  of  all  passenger  cars  as  ap  index  of  the  quantity 
of  steel  per  car. 

Table  7. — Average  Dry  Shipping  Weight  of  all  Passenger  Cars,  1920-1938 
[Weighted  by  new  car  registrations] 


Weight  in 

Weight  in 

Weight  in 

Year: 

Pounds 

Year: 

Pounds 

Year: 

Pounds 

1920.-_- 

2373 

1927 

---.     2486 

1934.... 

2691 

1921 

2223 

1928 

2587 

1935 

2791 

1922.... 

2324 

19^9 

....     2623 

1936.... 

2881 

1923-— 

....     2348 

1930 

....     2598 

1937.... 

2871 

1924 

2338 

1931 

2682 

1938 

2918 

1925-.. 

....     2356 

1932 

....     2769 

1926 

2412 

1933 

2599 

Source:  Datafrom  private  sources.    Approximately  the  same  data  for  1925  to  1938  is  obtained  from  Auto- 
mobile Facts  and  Figures  (1939),  p.  48,  by  dividing  average  price  per  car  by  average  price  per  pound. 

Chart  8 


110 


RELATION  OF  AUTOMOBILE  STEEL  PRICE  TO 
PASSENGER  CAR  WEIGHT 


mi* 

1925« 

,1928           i,j5 
1938.        I»6 

•  19M 

193*. 

.      •l924 
1930 

.937' 

19M» 

90  100  110  120 

AUTOMOBILE  STEEL  PRICE  IN  %  OF  PREVIOUS  YEAR 


^ 


>  Aj*  an^'  Aijtorroi>ife  f^-aflJtrt-jting  Ai^ocit 


Chart  8  compares  the  average  car  weight  with  an  index  of  typical  automotive 
steel  prices  "  in  order  to  determine  what  relationship  exists  between  them.  In 
order  to  eliminate  the  trend  in  both  series,  annual  percentage  changes  instead 
of  the  original  figures  are  plotted  against  each  other.  This  chart  does  not  dis- 
close any  relationship  of  car  weight  to  steel  prices.  This  lends  support  to  the 
conclusion  that  the  quantity  of  steel  used  per  car  depends  primarily  upon  technical 
factors  and  long-run  trends  in  taste  rather  than  upon  changes  in  the  price  of  steel. 
In  the  discussion  thus  far  there  has  been  no  consideration  of  the  elasticity  of 
the  demand  for  steel  in  the  accessories  and  parts  industry.  It  is  reasonable  to 
suppose,  however,  that  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  in  this  industry  is  about 
the  same  as  in  the  automobile  industry.  In  any  event,  since  the  value  of  the 
production  of  parts  and  accessories  is  only  about  one-seventh  of  the  value  of  the 
production  of  cars,  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  in  both  industries   taken 

»»  see  note  13  regarding  the  quality  of  the  data. 

1  Weights  from  Table  7,  prices  from  Table  10  in  the  Appendix. 

124491 — 41— pt. 


13996  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

toegther  is  not  much  different  from  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  in  the  au- 
mobile  industry  aloiie.'^ 

To  sum  up:  Tlie  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  used  as  a  raw  material  in  the 
automobile  industry  is  very  low,  probably  no  higher  than  .2  or  .3.  A  10%  reduc- 
tion in  the  price  of  automotive  steel,  if  passed  on  to  the  ultimate  consumer,  would 
lead  to  approximately  a  1.5%  increase  in  the  consumption  of  steel  directly  attrib- 
utable to  increased  car  sales,  and  possibly  to  a  very  slight  additional  increase 
directly  attributable  to  increased  weight  per  car.  Considering  these  combined 
effects,  a  10%  reduction  in  the  price  of  automotive  steel  would  probably  not 
increase  its  consumption  by  more  than  2%  or  3%. 

If  automotive  steel  sold  for  $60  a  ton  before  such  a  10%  price  reduction,  a  maxi- 
mum increase  of  3%  in  automotive  steel  consumption  resulting  therefrom  would 
mean  that  the  steel  producer  would  sell  1.03  tons  of  steel  where  he  formerly  sold 
one  ton,  but  for  such  increased  quantity  he  would  receive,  under  the  reduced  prices 
of  $54  a  ton,  only  $55.62  as  compared  with  his  earlier  sales  return  of  $00  for  a 
smaller  quantity.  Consequently  a  reduction  in  steel  prices  would  decrease  the 
gross  revenues,  increase  the  operating  expenses  and  greatly  reduce  the  net  income 
of  the  steel  industry. 

Automobile  sales  have  slumped  in  depression  because  of  reduced  consumer 
income  and  fear  and  uncertainty  of  the  future.  Against  these  tidal  forces  a  reduc- 
tion in  the  price  of  automotive  steel  could  have  no  significant  effect. 

Appendix 

Table  S.-^Production  of  Cars  and  of  Automobile  Parts  and  Accessories,  and  Total 
Number  of  Cars  Registered,  1921-1933 


Production  of  Auto 
Parts  and  Accessories 
at  Producers'  Prices ' 


(millions 
of  dollars) 


Production  of  Cars  at 
Producers'  Prices ' 


(millions 
of  dollars) 


Total  Number  of  Cars 
Eegistered  > 


(Millions) 


1921 
1922 
1923 
1924 
1925 
1926 
1927 
1928 
1929 
1930 
1931 
1932 


38.4 
55.2 
80.9 
76.6 
100.9 
100.0 
95.5 

92'.  7 
74.1 
62.0 
48.2 
51.8 


$1, 147 
1,596 
2.278 
2,034 
2,524 
2,679 
2,175 
2,557 
2.800 
1,643 
1,124 
627 
757 


100.0 
81.2 
95.4 

104.5 
61.3 
42.0 


10.5 
12.2 
15.1 
17.6 
19.9 
22.0 
23.1 
24.5 
26.5 
26.5 
25.8 
24.1 
23.9 


47.7 
55.5 
68.6 
80.0 
90.5 
100.0 
105.0 
111.4 
120.  5 
120.5 
117.3 
109.5 
108.2 


Sources:  ^  .    t.  ^ 

'  S.  Kuznets,  Commodity  Flow  and  Capital  Formation,  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research,  New 

York,  1938,  p.  137.    The  estimates  of  auto  parts  and  accessories  e.xcludo  original  equipment  used  in  the 

production  of  new  cars.    Data  not  available  for  years  subsequent  to  1933. 
2  Automobile  Fads  and  Figures,  Automobile  Manufacturers  Association,  1938,  p.  16. 


32  The  cost  of  steel  in  tools  and  dies  is  a  negligible  part  of  the  total  cost  of  an  automobile  and  is.  therefore, 
disregarded  in  this  study. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13997 

Table  9. — Automobile  Production  and  Steel  Consumption,  1923-19S8 


Year 

Production  of  Motor 
Vehicle.s ' 

Automotive  Steel  Con- 
sumption ' 

Steel  Con- 
sumption 
per  Motor 

Vehicle 
Produced' 

(thousands 
of  units) 

1929=100 

(thousands 
of  gross  ■ 
tons) 

1929=100 

(gross  tons) 

1923 

4180 
3738 
4428 
4506 
3580 
4601 
5622 
3510 
2472 
1431 
1986 
2870 
4120 
4616 
5016 
2655 

74.4 
66.5 
78.8 
80.1 

8l'.8 
100.0 
62.4 
44.0 
25.5 
35.3 
51.1 
73.3 
82.1 
89.2 
47.2 

4182 
2981 

5486 
4895 
6963 
6565 
4406 
3149 
1864 
3530 
4101 
6016 
6712 
6977 
3619 

63.9 
45.5 
74.7 

74^8 
106.4 
100.0 
67.3 
48.1 
28.5 
53.9 
62.7 
91.9 
102.2 
106.6 
55.3 

1.000 
797 

1924 

1925 ..        ..     ..     ..  . 

1.103 

1926... ..     ... 

1927 

1928. ..        ..     .. 

1929 

1930 

1931 . 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 ..     .  .. 

1936 -. 

1937 

1938.. .. 

1  statistical  Abstract  of  the  United  States,  1938,  p.  370.  1938  figure  from  Automobile  Facts  and  Figures,  1939, 
p.  4. 

2  Computed  by  apportioning  individual  hot-rolled  product  totals  on  the  basis  of  Tfon  Age  distribution 
reports  and  by  allocating  jobber  shipments  to  ultimate  consumers.  See  M.  W.  Worthing,  Distribution 
of  Steel  Products  to  Major  Consuming  Industries,  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  October  30,  1939. 

3  Considered  less  reliable  as  an  index  of  steel  used  per  car  than  the  average  dry  shipping  weight  shown  in 
Table  7. 

Table  10.— Steel  Prices,  1923-1938 
[Cents  per  poundl 


Year 

Hot-rolled 
Strip 

Hot-rolled 

Sheets  No. 

10  Gage 

Cold-rolled 
Sheets 

"Automotive 

Steel"  Price 

(average  of 

the  three 

prices)  i 

Iron  Age 
Composite 
Steel  Price 

1923 

3.04)S 
2.57 
2.27 
2.30 
2.26 
1.93 

L68 
1.54 
1.43 
1.58 
1.85 
1.85 
1.91 
2.35 
2.25 

2.96«i 
2.79 
2.45 
2.37 
2.20 
2.04 
2.12 
1.99 
1.86 
1.71 
1.62 
1.85 

l!92 
2.35 
2.25 

5. 19«S 
5.00 
4.39 
4.30 
4.17 
4.03 
4.06 
3.64 
3.13 
2.80 
2.48 
2.96 
2.95 
3.02 
3.49 
3.31 

3.73«i 
3.45 
3.04 
2.99 
2.88 
2.67 
2.69 
2.44 
2.18 
1.98 

2^22 
2.22 

2.n 

2.60 

2. 697< 
2  505 

1924 

1925 

2  334 

1926 

2  315 

1927 

2  202 

1928  ■ 

2  165 

1929       

2.209 
2.048 

1930       

1931 -  . 

1932 

1933 

1934 ... 

1935... 

1936 

2.077 

1937 ___ 

1938 

Source:  The  Iron  Age,  Annual  Statistical  Supplement,  reprinted  from  the  January  5, 1939,  issue,  pp.  8-10. 

1  A  simple  average  of  the  prices  of  these  three  steels  was  taken  as  the  average  automotive  steel  price  because 
(1)  they  are  the  most  important  kinds  of  steel  used  in  making  automobiles  and  (2)  they  are  used  in  about 
equal  amounts  per  car.    See  Table  11 


13998  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  11. — Net  Cost  of  Steel  Products  Used  in  Construction  of  Chevrolet  Sedan,  1938 
[F.  O.  B.  Flint  Price  $595.0O-New  York  Delivered  Price  $730) 


Steel  Products  Used 

Analysis  of  Steel  Cost  July  14, 
1938 

Product 

Weight  in 
pounds 

Price  at  Detroit 

Cost  of  product 
for  one  auto 

144.0 

162.0 

23.0 

15.8 

45.0 

17.0 

278.0 

554.0 

531.0 

98.9 

509.2 

0.2 

23.6 

0.9 

284.2 

0.6 

0.6 

19.0 

6.0 

1.0 

6.0 

2.3 

7.8 

70.8 

$20.  50   Q.  T. 

20.  50    Q.  T. 
3. 85   per  100# 
2.32   perl00# 
3.15   perl00# 

37.32    O.  T. 

45.00    Q.T. 
3.35   perlOO# 
2.925perl00# 
3.77   per  loo* 
2.65   perlOO# 

30.29   periOO# 
4.  575  per  100# 
4.  575  per  100# 
3.60   perl00# 

38.42   Q.T. 

99. 54    Q.  T. 

11.75    Q.T. 
3. 47   per  100# 
9. 58   per  100# 
3.47   porlOO* 

61.32    Q.T. 
3. 82   per  100# 
3.77   perlOO# 

$1  31 

Pig  Iron— Malleable 

1  48 

0  89 

Plates 

0.37 

Bars — cold  drawn 

1.42 

Sheet  bars 

0.28 

Billets — forging                                -         ... 

5.68 

Sheets— cold  rolled                  

18.56 

Sheets — hot  rolled        -    .. 

15.53 

3.73 

13.49 

0.06 

1.08 

0.04 

9.95 

0.01 

0.03 

0.10 

Nails      - 

0.21 

0.10 

0.21 

Wire  rods 

0.05 

0.30 

2.64 

Total  products  listed                         -  .    

2800.1 

>  $77. 42 

«  $77.42  is  about  13%  of  $595  and  about  10%  of  $730. 

Source:  Data  on  steel  products  used  were  taken  from  MiU  and  Factory,  June,  1938,  p.  96,  and  were  supple- 
mented by  conversations  with  persons  in  the  automobile  industry.  Data  on  prices  were  prepared  by  United 
States  Steel  Corporation. 


Table  12.- 


^Automobile  Prices,  Automotive  Steel  Prices  and  Prices  of  Manufactured 
Goods,  1919-38 


Retail  Passenger  Car  Price  > 

Index  of 
Wholesale 

Prices  of 
Manufactured 

Qoods  > 
(1913=100) 

Year 

(dollars  per 
car) 

(cents  per 
pound) 

Automotive 

Steel  Price  > 

(cents  per 

pound) 

1925                                          

•$1007 
943 
977 
911 
843, 
798 
767 
723 
630 
664 
658 
687 
704 
779 

42.70 

39.1 

39.3 

35.2 

32.1 

30.7 

28.4 

26.1 

24.2 

24.7 

23.6 

23.8 

24.6 

20.  7 

3.04^ 
2i.99 

2!  67 
2.69 
3.44 
V>.18 
1.98 
1.89 
2.22 
2.22 
2.28 
2.73 
2.60 

162.4 

1926 

157.6 

1927                            . 

152.0 

1928 

153.1 

151.5 

140.4 

123.? 

1932           . 

111.6 

1933- 

113.8 

1934 

126.0 

130.9 

1936 

130.3 

1937 

139.8 

1938. 

130.9 

Sources: 

1  Taken  from  Autojnobile  Facts  and  Figures,  A.  M.  A.  1939,  p.  48.  Kepresents  delivered  price  at 
factory  of  the  cheapest  four  or  five  passenger  closed  models  of  each  make,  weighted  by  new  car 
rcKistration. 

>  From  Table  10. 

» Taken  from  F.  C.  Mills,  Prices  on  Recession  and  Recovery.  National  Bureau  of  Economic 
Kus<iarch,  1936.  Appendix  III,  pp.  491-2.  Fieures  for  1936-1938  from  National  Bmocu  of  Econo»ic 
Uc:Jc:ircU. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  13999 

Exhibit  No.  1414 

AN  ANALYSIS  OF  THE  DEMAND    FOR  STEEL  IN  THE   RAILROAD 
INDUSTRY 

This  is  an  analysis  prepared  by  the  Special  Economic  Research  Section  of  the 
United  States  Steel  Corporation,  composed  of  Messrs.  Edward  T.  Dickinson,  Jr., 
Ernest  M.  Doblin,  H.  Gregg  Lewis,  Jacob  L.  Mosak,  Mandal  R.  Segal,  Dwight  B. 
Yntema  and  Miss  Marion  W.  Worthing.  The  work  of  this  group  was  under  the 
supervision  of  Theodore  O.  Yntema,  Professor  of  Statistics,  University  of  Chicago. 
This  report  was  written  by  Mandal  R.  Segal  and  has  had  the  benefit  of  suggestions 
from  other  members  of  the  staff.  It  is  issued  by  United  States  Steel  Corporation. 
November  1,  1939. 

contents 
I.  Purpose. 
II.  Findings. 

lU.  The  Railroad  Industry. 
-  IV.  Factors  Affecting  Steel  Consumption  by  the  Railroads. 

A.  Freight  Traffic. 

B.  Passenger  Traffic. 
O.  Financial  Condition. 

1.  Operating  Revenues  and  Profits. 

2.  Source  of  Funds  (or  Capital  Investment. 
V.  Demand  for  Steel  by  the  Railroads. 

A.  Maintenance  and  Capital  Expenditures. 

1.  Maintenance  Expenditures. 

2.  Capital  Expenditures. 

B.  Steel  Consumption  by  the  Railroads. 

C.  The  Influence  of  the  Price  of  Steel  on  Its  Consumption  by  the  Railroad  Industry. 
VI.  Summary.  (, 

I.  Purpose 

The  purpose  of  this  study  is  to  review  the  factors  which  influence  the  railroads' 
demand  for  steel,  to  analyze  their  relative  importanc?,  and  in  particular  to  ap- 
praise the  role  of  price  in  the  consumption  of  steel  by  the  railroads. 

II.  Findings 

(1)  The  railroads'  demand  for  steel  is  derived  from  the  demand  for  railroad 
services,  which  in  turn  depends  primarily  upon  the  national  income  and  the  com- 
petition from  alternative  means  of  transportation. 

(2)  Due  to  the  durability  of  railroad  equipment,  changes  in  the  demand  for 
railroad  services  generate  much  greater  fluctuations  in  the  demand  for  equipment 
and  hence  in  the  consumption  of  steel  by  the  railroads. 

(3)  Capital  expenditures  for  rolling  stock  and  other  equipment  requiring  steel 
are  ultimately  dependent  on  the  demand  for  rail  transportation;  but  in  the  short 
run  they  are  determined  by  th§  adequacy  of  existing  facilities  for  current  traffic 
needs  and  by  the  funds  available  for  such  outlays.  Whep  the  demand  for  railroad 
services  declines,  there  is  less  need  for  capital  expenditures  on  rolling  stock  and 
other  equipment  which  require  steel  in  their  production,  and  also  railroads  have 
less  funds  available  for  such  expenditures. 

(4)  The  consumption  of  steel  for  maintenance  purposes  is  closely  related  to  the 
volume  of  traffic  currently  handled  by  the  roads. 

(5)  Price  is  of  minor  importance  in  determining  the  consumption  of  steel  by 
the  railroads.  This  is  emphatically  true  of  aggregate  steel  purchases  over  a  con- 
siderable period  of  time.     It  follows  from  two  facts: 

(a)  the  demand  for  transportation  services  for  freight  and  for  passengers 
certainly  has  a  low  elasticity,  probably  leas  than  unity.  This  means  that  a 
given  percentage  change  in  rates  probably  will  have  a  smaller  proportionate 
effect  on  the  volume  of  railroad  services.  The  effects  of  rate  changes,  how- 
ever, may  vary  among  railroads  and  different  sections  of  tlie  country. 

(b)  the  cost  of  steel  is  a  comparative!}^  small  fraction  of  the  total  cost  of 
transportation  service,  and  consequently  has  little  effect  on  the  price  (i.  e., 
rates)  or  volume  of  railroad  services. 

(6)  Even  with  respect  to  cyclical  timing  of  steel  purchases,  price  is  not  a  major 
influence.  Capital  equipment  is  purchased  when  it  is  needed  and  can  be  profitably 
employed,  and  when  funds  are  available.  Maintenance  is  determirfed  partly  by 
the  requirements  of  traffic  and  partly  by  the  revenues  w-hich  can  be  used  for  this 
purpose.  In  a  depression,  purchases  are  reduced  to  conform  to  current  needs. 
In  their  dire  financial  straits  the  railroads  are  in  no  position  to  speculate  on  possible 
fluctuations  in  steel  prices  by  making  purchases  not  required  by  current  needs. 


14000  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

(7)  The  low  consumption  of  steel  by  the  railway  industry  in  the  last  decade 
has  been  due  to  the  declining  trend  in  rail  transportation,  the  severe  depression 
in  business  and  the  poor  financial  conditions  of  the  railroads.  No  conceivable 
reduction  in  price  of  steel  to  the  railroads  could  have  counteracted  these  forces  to 
a  substantial  extent. 

III.  The  Railroad  Industry 

Any  attempt  to  determine  the  railroads'  demand  for  steel  must  start  with  some 
analysis  of  the  railroad  industrj'.  As  the  chief  agency  for  transportation,  rail- 
roads have  been  indispensable  in  the  national  economy.  They  are  also  of  great 
importance  as  sources  of  employment,  investment  and  consumption. 

The  railroads  have  recently  been  in  a  stage  of  transition  from  an  expanding  to  a 
declining  industry.  The  periods  of  experimentation  between  1830  and  1850,  of 
rapid  expansion  from  1850  to  1890,  and  of  sub.sequent  development  of  particular 
areas  and  of  feeder  and  cross  lines  have,  since  the  World  War,  been  followed  by  an 
era  of  shrinkage  in  railroad  mileage,  severe  competition  from  other  transportation 
agencies,  and  declining  trends  irroperating  revenues.  In  recent  years  the  financial 
position  of  most  railroads  has  been  seriously  impaired;  approximately  one-third 
of  the  railroad  mileage  of  the  United  States  is  in  bankruptcy,'  and  in  1938  only  a 
few  roads  earned  all  their  fixed  charges. 

IV.  Factors  Affecting  Steel  Consumption  by  the  Railroads 

The  decline  in  railroad  operations  has  been  accompanied  by  a  decline  in  the 
railroads'  consumption  of  steel.  The  railroads  had  long  been  the  leading  customers 
of  the  steel  industry,  but  during  the  past  ten  years  the  purchases  of  steel  by  the 
railroad  industry  have  declined  absolutely  and  relatively.  Whereas  in  1923,  the 
railroads  consumed  approximately  25.4%  of  k\l  the  finished  steel  produced  and 
ranked  first  as  a  consuming  group,  by  1932  they  consumed  approximately  10% 
of  the  finished  steel  produced  and  ranked  third  as  a  consuming  group.  In  1938 
they  consumed  only  6.1%  of  the  total  finished  steel  produced  in  the  United  States.'' 

Railroads  use  a  variety  of  steel  products  for  many  different  purposes.  Their 
purchases  range  from  rails,  plates  and  structural  shapes  to  bolts,  nuts,  washers 
and  rivets.  In  general,  steel  is  now  consumed  by  the  railroads  in  the  form  of  new 
locomotives  and  cars  and  as  material  for  the  maintenance  of  way,  structure  and 
equipment. 

The  demand  for  steel  by  the  railroads  is  derived  from  the  demand  for  freight 
and  passenger  tra'nsportation  services,  which  exhibit  marked  cyclical  fluctuations. 
It  is  this  fact  which  accounts  for  the  great  fluctuations  in  the  purchases  of  steel 
by  railroads.  These  fluctuations  are  further  intensified  by  the  durability  of  the 
steel  products  used  by  the  railroads,  and  by  the  limitations  of  impaired  financial 
condition  and  the  reduced  operating  revenues  experienced  in  periods  of  depression 
by  the  railroads.  These  relationships  are  set  forth  in  more  detail  in  the  follow- 
ing analysis. 

A.    FREIGHT    TRAFFIC 

Freight  traffic  rose  gradually  during  the  1920's,  reaching  a  peak  of  450  billion 
ton-miles  of  railroad  revenue  freight  in  1929.^  In  the  depression  low  of  1932  it 
fell  to  235  billion  ton-miles.  By  1937  freight  traffic  had  recovered  to  363  billion 
ton-miles,  but  for  the  year  ended  June  30,  1938,  it  declined  again  to  313  billion 
ton-miles,* 

It  has  long  been  recognized  that  freight  car  loadings  are  closely  related  to  indus- 
trial production.  This  is  to  be  expected,  for  frg'ight  car  loadings  include  mainly 
industrial  products  and  industrial  raw  material  such  as  coal,  coke,  forest  products 
and  ore.  Chart  1  shows  this  close  relationship  between  industrial  production 
and  miscellaneous  and  merchandise  freight  car  loadings.*  By  statistical  analysis 
the  National  Resources  Committee  found  that  fluctuations  in  freight  traffic  were 
almost  completely  explained  by  fluctuations  in  industrial  production. « 

The  evidence  points  strongly  to  the  conclusion  that  the  demand  for  rail  freigtlit 
transportation  has  a  rather  low  elasticity.  First,  the  very  close  dependence  of 
rail   freight   traffic   on   business   activity   lends   support   to   this   conclusion. 

1  See  infru,  Table  2. 

'  See  Appendix,  Table  7. 

'  Soe  Appendix,  Table  8. 

<  Se"^  Appendix,  Table  8. 

»  See  also  Appendix,  Table  9.  Miscellaneous  and  merchandise  G-  c.  1.)  freight  car  loadings  were  used, 
since  they  cover  industrial  products  more  directly  than  the  combine^  index  of  freight  car  loadings'  which 
includes  agricultural  products  and  livestock. 

•  Industrial  Committee  of  the  National  Resources  Committee,  Patterns  of  Resource  Use  (1939).  p.  99.  It 
was  found  that  ninety-seven  percent  of  the  variation  in  freight  traffic  was  explained  by  variations  in  indus- 
trial production  and  a  time  trend. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        14001 

Second,  the  demand  for  freight  transportation  is  derived  from  the  demand  for  the 
goods  to  be  transported  and  must  have  a  low  elasticity  because  transportation 
charges  are  not  usually  a  large  fraction  of  total  value  of  goods  carried.  The 
availability  of  substitute  means  of  transportation  tends  to  increase  the  elasticity 
of  demand  for  rail  freight  service,  but  it  should  be  noted  that  the  possibilities  of 
substitution  are  limited  by  technical  obstacles.  Furthermore,  from  a  broader 
point  of  view  the  substitution  of  one  transportation  agency  for  another  does  not 
greatly  affect  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  total  transportation  or  for  the  steel 
consumed  by  all  transportation  agencies. 

Although  the  movements  of  the  two  series  have  been  much  alike,  freight  car 
loadings  have  not  kept  pace  with  industrial  production,  especially  since  the 
depression  low  of  1932.  The  failure  of  the  freight  car  loadings  to  recover  as  rapidly 
as  industrial  production  since  1932  has  been  due  largely  to  the  diversion  of  traffic 

Chart  1 


INDUSTRIAL  PRODUCTION  AND  M'D'SE  AND  MISC.  CAR  LOADINGS 

l-tUtHAL  RESERVE  INDEXES  ADJUSTED  FOR  SFASONAL  VARIATION 
1923  .  1925  =  100 

180 

180 
160 

140^ 
120    1 

100  i 

80      2 
a 

60      ^ 
40 
20 
0 

160 
w     140 

UJ 

«    120 
z    100 

S      80 

o 

5      60 
40 
20 

A 

1 

NOUSTRIAL 

C>. 

>y^ 

>JSS 

®^ 

r^ 

z\ 

V 

'z 

^ 

^ 

^v 

\ 

^ 

A 

;? 

^ 

7 

\ 

L 

U 

-^ 

) 

kvx 

V. 

G 

iR  LOADING. 

> 

M'D'SE  (LCU.^ 
CAR  LOADINGS 

&>«>.' >^<W 

1924        1926        1928        1930        1932        1934        1936        1938 

from  the  railroads  to  trucks,  waterways,  and  pipe  lines.  This  shift  from  the 
railroads  to  the  other  commercial  forms  of  transportation  is  evident  from  the 
following  table: 

Table  \.— Distribution  of  Freight  Traffic  by  Commercial  Agencies,  1926  and  1937 


Agency 

Amount    Millions 
of  Revenue  Ton- 
Miles 

Percent  of  Total 
Ton-Miles 

1926 

1937 

1926 

1937 

Steam  Railways 

447, 443 
23,530 
90,038 
9,543 
21,700 
1,3131 
Nil/ 

362,815 

43.  380 
93,244 
16,883 

44,  793 

"3 

Percent 
75.4 
3.9 
15.2 
1.6 
3.7 
0.2 

Percent 
64  6 

Intercity  Trucks 

7  7 

Great  Lakes       

16  6 

Electric  Railways! 

Airways                / 

0.1 

Total..     

593,  567 

561,815 

100.0 

Source:  Report  of  Committee,  Appointed  Sept.  20,  1938,  by  the  President  of  the  United  States  to  Sub 
Recommendations  upon  the  General  Transportation  Situation  (1938),  pp.  44-6. 


14002  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

These  data  show  that  the  proportion  of  the  commercial  freight  business  handled 
by  the  railroads  declined  from  three-fourths  of  the  total  in  1926  to  less  than  two- 
thirds  in  1937.  While  the  railroads  handled  84.6  billion  ton-miles  of  freight  less 
in  1937  than  in  1926,  the  intercity  trucks,  the  waterways,  and  the  pipe  lines 
increased  their  freight  ton-miles  by  19.9,  10.5  and  23.1  bilUon  ton-miles,  respec- 
tively. In  percentage  terms,  there  was  a  decrease  of  18.9%  in  the  freight  ton-miles 
handled  by  the  railways  between  1926  and  1937. 

B.  PASSENGER  TRAFFIC 

Passenger  traffic  has  exhibited  a  severely  decUning  trend  since  1923,  when 
revenue  passenger  miles  had  reached  an  all-time  peak  (excluding  the  period  of 
federal  control) .  By  1937  passenger  traffic  had  dropped  35%  from  its  1923  level, 
in  spite  of  an  increase  of  16%  in  population  and  a  rise  of  24%  in  consumers' 
income  (in  1936  dollars).''  This  marked  downward  trend  in  passenger  traffic  has 
been  due  mainly  to  the  expansion  of  other  forms  of  transportation,  primarily  the 
automobile;  from  1923  to  1937 -automobile  passenger  car  registrations  increased 
88%*   and  passenger  car  mileage  rose  more  than  50%. 

Railroad  passenger  traffic  has  been  greatly  influenced  by  consumers*  incomes.' 
A  recent  study  of  the  National  Resources  Committee  found  that  consumers' 
income  was- the  most  important  factor  in  explaining  the  variations  in  passenger 
traffic  1"  and  that  railroad  fates  were,  much  less  important.  Its  findings  indicate 
that  the  demand  for  passenger  service  was  inelastic  in  that  a  one  per  cent  reduc- 
tion in  rates  would  induce  about  a  one-half  of  one  per  cent  increase  in  passenger 
traffic."  This  inference  may  not  necessarily  be  the  same  for  all  railroads  or  for 
different  sections  of  the  country  but  appears  to  be  warranted  for  total  passenger 
transportation. 

Consumers'  income  and  competition  from  other  transportation  media,  then,  are 
the  most  important  factors  explaining  fluctuations  in  passenger  traffic.  In  the 
depression  of  the  early  thirties  rail  passenger  traffic  fell  to  extremely  low  levels 
because  the  cyclical  decline  in  consumers'  incomes  was  reinforced  by  the  continued 
shift  of  traffic  to  other  media  of  transportation.  In  1933,  revenue  passenger  miles 
were  less  than  50%  of  their  average  level  during  the  twenties;  in  the  1937  recovery 
that  foUowed,  although  consumers'  income  (in  1936  dollars)  surpassed  its  1929 
level,  rail  passenger  traffic  failed  by  21%  to  reach  its  1929  volume."  In  the  last 
few  years  the  volume  of  passenger  traffic  would  probably  have  been  even  lower 
had  it  not  been  for  marked  improvements  in  the  quality  of  service. 

C.  FINANCIAL  CONDITION 

1.  Operating  Revenues  and  Profits. — Since  1926  the  financial  condition  of  rail- 
roads has  become  progressively  more  critical.  This  is  mainly  attributable  to  a 
decUne  in  the  volume  of  traffic  which  became  marked  beginning  with  1930.  Total 
operating  revenues  reached  a  peak  of  6.4  billion  dollars  in  1926  and  declined  to  a 
low  of  3.1  billion  dollars  in  1933.  Although  in  1937  revenues  recovered  to  4.2 
billion  dollars,  35%  above  the  1933  level,  they  fell  again  in  1938  to  3.6  billion, 
only  15%  above  the  depression  low.'* 

This  drastic  decline  in  total  operating  revenues,  combined  with  the  smaller 
reduction  in  operating  expenses  and  the  slower  decline  in  taxes  and  fixed  charges, 
caused  larger  deficits."  Net  income  in  1929  amounted  to  about  900  million  dol- 
lars, and  dropped  to  a  deficit  of  140  million  in  1932.  There  were  deficits  again 
in  1933  and  1934,  and  an  insignificant  net  income  in  1935.  After  moderate  earn- 
ings in  1936  and  1937,  the  deficit  reached  over  120  milHon  dollars  in  1938.  Divi- 
dend rates"  in  1929  and  1930  were  6%  of  the  capital  stock  outstanding,  but  in 
1932  they  were  only  1.12%,  and  even  in  the  best  recent  year  not  higher  than 
2.11%." 

'  See  Appendix,  Table  10. 

«  See  A.ppondlx,  Table  11. 

•  See  Appendix,  Table  10. 

'•  Cf.  National  Resources  Oommlttee,  op.  eit.,  pp.  00-1  and  99. 

"  Ibid. 

'«  See  Appendix,  Table  10. 

>•  See  Appendix,  Table  12. 

i<  See  Table  2  in  text  and  Appendix,  Table  12. 

"  See  Appendix,  Table  13. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14003 


Table  2. — Railroad  Operating  Revenues,  Net  Income  and  Mileage  in  Receivership, 

1928-38 


Year 

Operating 
Revenues  i 
{thousands 
of  dollars) 

Net  Income » 
(thousands 
of  dollars) 

Percent  of  Total 
Railroad  Mile- 
age Operated 
by  Receivers 
or  Trustees « 

1928 

$6,111,738 
6,  279,  621 
5,  281, 197 
4, 188, 343 
3, 126, 760 
3, 095, 404 
3,  271,  667 

3,  451,  929 

4,  052,  734 
4. 166, 069 
3, 565,  000 

$786.  824 
898, 807 
623,907 
134,  762 
139,  204 
«  5,  863 
16,887 
7,539 
164,630 
.     98,068 
123,000 

2.02% 

1929 

1930 

1931 

1932 

8.71 
16.24 
16  64 

1933 

1934 

1935 

26  87 

1936 

27  67 

1937 

1938 

Sources: 

'  Figures  (or  operating  revenues  and  net  income  cover  Class  I  railroads  only,  while  mileage  in  receiver- 
ship applies  to  all  railroads. 

»  Based  on  Reports  of  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  and  Association  of  American  Railroads,  Bureau 
of  Railway  Economics  (A  Review  of  Railway  Operations  in  19SS). 

•  Based  on  Reports  of  Interstate  Commerce  Commission. 

•  Deficit. 

The  uufortunate  financial  condition  of  the  railroads  is  forceably  demonstrated 
by  the  growing  percentage  of  mileage  operated  by  receivers  or  trustees.  Table  2 
shows  an  uninterrupted  rise  from  2.02%  in  1928  to  30.98%  in  the  middle  of  1938 
in  spite  of  some  recovery  in  operating  revenues  and  net  income  between  1933  and 
1937. 

In  part,  the  financial  difficulties  of  the  railroads  have  been  due  to  the  inflexi- 
bility of  certain  costs.  From  1921  to  1929  an  average  of  11.0  cen^s  of  every  doUar 
of  operating  revenue  went  to  pay  fixed  charges;  then  from  1930  to  1937,  this 
average  rose  63%  to  17.9  cents."  In  dollar  terms,  the  expenditures  for  interest 
on  debt  remained  fairly  stable  in  the  depression;  from  518  million  dollars  in  1931, 
this  expenditure  rose  to  slightly  over  525  million  dollars  in  1932,  and  graduaUv 
feU  to  491  million  in  1937.i' 

Hourly  wage  rates  have  exhibited  similar  inflexibility.  The  average  hourly 
wage  in  1929  was  66.6  cents;  after  a  drop  to  a  low  of  62.9  cents  in  1933,  it  rose  to 
68.6  cents  in  1935  and  70.9  cents  in  1937.18  Since  approximately  45%  of  the 
average  operating  revenue  dollar  is  expended  for  wages,'"  this  comparative  inflex- 
ibility in  wage  rates  has  adversely  aflFected  the  earnings  and  general  financial 
position  of  the  railroads. 

2.  Source  of  Funds. — During  the  relatively  prosperous  period  of  the  twenties, 
about  70%  of  the  funds  used  by  the  railroads  for  capital  investments  were  ob- 
tained from  income,  approximately  25%  from  the  issue  of  securities,  and  the 
relatively  small  remainder  from  reduction  of  working  capital.  During  the  period 
from  1931  to  1937,  not  only  was  income  available  for  investment  greatly  reduced, 
but  the  capital  market  was  practically  eliminated  as  a  source  of  funds  for  capital 
investment;  in  fact,  during  this  period  more  securities  were  retired  by  the  railroads 
than  issued.  The  following  table  shows  the  amount  and  the  sources  of  the  funds 
for  capital  purposes  from  1921  to  1937: 

"  Report  of  the  Emergencv  Board  to  the  President  (October,  1938),  p.  16. 

"  See  Appendix,  Table  13. 

»  Ibid. 

"  Report  of  the  Emergencv  Board  to  the  President  (October,  1938),  p.  30. 


14004        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  3. — Funds  for  Capital  Purposes,  Class  I  Railroads  and  Their  Lessor  Com- 
panies, 1921-1937 


Period 

From  Income 

From     Reduction 
in  Working  Cap- 
ital 

From  Securities 

Total 
(millions 
of  dol- 
lars; 

Average 
Annual 
Total 

Millions 
of  dol- 
lars 

Percent 

Millions 
of  dol- 
lars 

Percent 

Millions 
of  dol- 
lars 

Percent 

(millions 
of  dol- 
lars) 

1921-30 

1931-37_ - 

$6, 003. 4 
1, 402. 4 

69. 10% 
8G.29 

$555. 1 
414.6 

6. 39% 
25.51 

$2, 129.  5 
U91.8 

24. 51% 
•11.80 

$8, 688. 0 
1, 625. 2 

$888.8 
232.2 

Source:  Compiled  from  Tables  submitted  to  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  by  J.  W. 
Ballinger  III.    Record  Vol.  Ill,  p.  404. 

On  an  annual  basis,  funds  for  capital  investments  derived  from  income,  from 
reduction  in  working  capital,  and  from  the  sale  of  securities  averaged  approxi- 
mately 868  million  dollars  during  the  twenties,  while  the  annual  average  from 
the  same  sources  during  the  period  fram  1931  to  1937  amounted  to  about  232 
million,  only  about  27%  of  the  level  during  the  more  prosperous  years. 

Apart  from  the  expenditures  for  capital  investment  during  the  period  from  1921 
to  1937,  a  further  amount  of  24.7  billion  dollars  was  necessary  to  finance  mainte- 
nance (excluding  depreciation  and  retirement).  Of  this  amount  about  18.2  billion 
was  spent  during  the  1921  to  1930  period  and  6.5  billion  in  the  1931  to  1937  period. 
On  an  annual  basis,  expenditures  in  the  earlier  period  were  1.8  billion  as  compared 
with  0.9  billion  dollars  during  the  depression  years.^" 

V.  Demand  for  Steel  by  the  Railroads 


A.  maintenance  and  capital  expenditures 

As  a  result  of  the  decline  in  traffic  and  revenues,  the  railroads  curtailed  their 
expenditures  for  maintenance  and  capital  equipment.  Not  only  has  there  been 
less  need  for  equipment  and  materials,  but  there  have  -been  less  funds  available 
to  purchase  these  materials  and  equipment.  Table  4  shows  the  drastic  curtail- 
ments in  the  subdivisions  of  the  two  major  groups  of  expenditures: 


Table  4. 


-Class  I — Railroad  Maintenance  and  Capital  Expenditures,  1923-1938 
(Millions  of  dollars] 


Maintenance  Expenditures 

Capital  Expenditures 

Year 

Ways 
and 
struc- 
tures 

Equip- 
ment 

Total 

Ways 
and 
struc- 
tures 

Equip- 
ment 

Total 

1923    - 

$813.7 
792.7 
816.4 
866.8 
868.6 
837.9 
855.4 
705.5 
530.6 
351.2 
322.3 
365.3 
394.0 
454.8 
495.6 
420.2 

$1, 465. 2 

i;259!8 

1,283.1 

1.219.1 

1.166.9 

1,202.9 

1,019.3 

817.0 

618.9 

598.  7 

637.9 

681.9 

783.0 

826.7 

676.5 

$2,278.9 
2, 052.  7 
2, 070.  2 
2, 149.  9 
2,087.7 
2, 004.  8 
2,  058.  3 
1,724.8 
1,  347.  6 
970.1 
921.0 
1,003.2 
1,075.9 
1,237.8 
1,  322.  3 
1,096.7 

$377. 4 
381.1 
410.1 
513.2 
482.9 
452.4 
532.4 
644.3 
288.8 
130.8 

120!? 
109.0 
139.9 
186.9 
111.5 

$681.7 
493.6 
338.1 
371.9 
288.7 
224.3 
321.3 
328.3 
73.1 
36.4 
15.5 
92.0 
79.3 
159.1 
322.9 
115.4 

$1,059.1 

1924 

874.7 

1925 

748.2 

1926 

885.1 

1927                        -' 

771.6 

676.7 

1929 - 

853.7 

1930 

872.6 

1931 

361.9 

1932                                  ... 

167.2 

104.0 

212.7 

1935 

188.3 

1936 

299.0 

1937 

509.8 

226.9 

Source:  Reports  of  Carriers  to  Bureau  of  Railway  Economics  and  published  by  Association  of  American 
Railroads. 


JO  Testimony  of  J.  W.  Ballinger,  III,  before  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee  May  17,  1939. 
Due  to  the  diflerences  ia  methods  of  computation,  these  figures  differ  slightly  from  those  given  in  text  in 
Table  4. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14005 


1.  Maintenance  Expenditures. — Of  the  two  groups  of  expenditures,  total  main- 
tenance outlays  constitute  about  40%  of  operating  expenses,  and,  in  general, 
absorb  one-third  of  total  operating  revenues.  If  the  annual  average  from  1921  to 
1928  is  taken  as  100,  the  index  for  maintenance  expenditures  fell  to  44.3  in  1933 
and  recovered  to  63.6  in  1937.2'  In  actual  money  terms,  maintenance  expendi- 
tures declined  from  over  2  billion  dollars  in  1929  to  less  than  a  billion  dollars  in 
1932  and  1933;  they  made  some  recovery  in  1937,  reaching  1.3  billion  dollars. 

Maintenance  expenditures  decreased  more  in  the  depression  than  revenue 
ton-miles  as  shown  in  Chart  2.     From  1929  to  1933  such  expenditures  dropped 

Chart  2 


RAILROAD  TRAFFIC  AND  EXPENDITURES 

CLASS  I  RAILROADS 

900 
800 
700 
600 
500 
400 

300 

CO 
UJ 

d      200 

Z 

z 
o 

»- 

bu       100 
O        90 

60 
^        70 
O        60 
-        50 
5        40 

30 

20 
10 

91) 

e.o 

7.0 
6.0 
5.0 
4.0 
3.0 

CO 

-1 

§ 

0.8       V) 
0.7       Z 
0.6       2 

0.5       d 
ca 
0.4 

03 
02 

0.1 

**" 

_ 

^ 

s 

k 

;vEr 

UETO^ 

-Ml 

ES 

y 

\^ 

\J 

*> 

*w 

\ 

-" 

V 

\ 

\ 

MA 
EXP 

\ 

NTE 
END 
DOU 

ITU 
JWS 

CE 
?ES 

y 

,> 

\ 

^T 

^* 

h^ 

^A 

V 

/ 

1 

V 

// 

UCAPII 

AL  EXPENDITUR 

ES 

lOLLA 

«S) 

11 

1 

rN 

ll 

[ 

/ 

^ 

Scum.  Aaoca 

iliiiiisliiiili; 

3 
% 

55%,  while  traffic  in  terms  of  revenue  ton-miles  shrank  by  only  48%  from  1929 
to  its  1932  low.22  Moreover,  traffic  resumed  the  upswing  one  year  before  these 
expenditures  turned  up  again.  Roughly  the  course  of  both  series  is  similar,  for 
the  decline  in  railway  services  meant  a  reduction  in  the  need  for  railroad  mainte- 
nance at  about  the  same  rate.  The  fact  that  maintenance  expenditures  decHned 
more  rapidly  than  traffic  is  explained  by  practices  which  Commissioner  Splawn 
of  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  has  called  "continued  skimping."  ^^ 
In  the  upswing  beginning  in  1934,  maintenance  expenditures  on  the  roads  were  not 
expanded  at  the  same  rate  as  traffic  represented  by  ton-miles.  In  1937  traffic 
was  some  20%  below  the  1929  level,  while  these  expenditures  were  35%  lower. 

n  See  Appendix,  Table  14. 

"  Ibid. 

»  Quoted  in  the  Report  of  the  Emergency  Board  to  the  President,  (193S),  p.  12. 


14006 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


The  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  in  the  Fifteen  Percent  Case,  1937-1938. 
summarized  the  evidence  on  maintenance  as  follows: 

"During  the  period  of  recovery  in  railroad  traffic  and  earnings  since  1932, 
maintenance  continued  to  be  governed  mainly  by  immediate  needs  dependent  on 
volume  of  traffic.  A  year  or  so  ago,  when  the  outlook  seemed  more  encouraging, 
a  number  of  roads  expanded  their  maintenance  programs,  but  curtailed  them  again 
sharply  in  latter  part  of  1937,  when  operating  costs  increased  and  traflSc  declined. 
The  cumulative  burden  of  deferred  maintenance  dating  from  the  depression 
therefore  is  still  present.  *  *  *  Deferred  maintenance  of  structures  appears 
to  be  particularly  extensive."'^ 

2.  Capital  Expenditures. — The  decline  in  the  demand  for  railroad  services 
affected  gross  capital  expenditures  far  more  drastically  than  expenditures  for 


Chart  3 

1000 
900 
800 
700 
600 
500 
400 
300 

to 

%      200 

-J 
§ 

S      100 
to        80 
S        70 

2     eo 

d       50 

=^        40 

30 

20 

10 

GROSS  CAPITAL  EXPENDITURE? 

CLASS  I  RAILROADS 

1000 
900 
800 
700 
000 
500 
400 
300 

CO 

20O     1 

O 

o 

'^  ^ 

80        (rt 

eo     2 

50       d 

30 

If 
20 

)0 

' 

— 

^ 

\ 

\ 

/ 

r 

- 

^> 

.-*' 

s 

^. 

WAYS  AN 
STRUaUR 

3 
ES 

\ 

/' 

\ 

/ 

\ 
\ 

\ 

\ 

\ 

\, 

i 

'/ 

\ 

>/ 

\ 

\ 

\ 

EQU 

IPM 

NTl 

k        1 

\; 

V 

i 

SblKi:  AsilxiX 

maintenance  (Chart  2 — Sec  Table  4  and  Appendix,  'J'able  8).  Capital  expendi- 
tures t;hrank  from  an  a\erage  of  843  million  dollars  in  the  eight-year  period  1923- 
1930  to  only  259  million  dollars  in  the  1931-1938  period,  a  decline  of  nearly  70%. 
These  expendituriis  fell  from  873  million  dollars  in  1930  to  362  million  in  1931,  a 
drop  of  almost  f)0%  in  one  year. 

The  capital  outlay.s  for  new  equipment  exliibited  greater  lluctuatious  than  those 
for  way  and  .structures,  as  shown  in  Chart  3.     Expenditures  for  capital  equipment 

"  Fifteen  J^crcerU  Canf.  {I'U  l-'arlf.  ISV.  1.  C.  (.;.  U26,  41.  «i).  as  »  rcsiU*.  of  Iheatv  ^h:lri>  niiruiihueuts  Id 
niiiiiUonancc,  ihero  hfi.sboe,ii  c<iusi<lerabln  unflerin!iiDtt!n:\iK!e  on  tho  rikilroiwis  in  lorms  of  past  i>erformrtiices. 
In  »  QU(«tionn).iro  uimlyMS  liisi  yeiir  tLo  JnUiisUle  Comiucrco  Couinu&sion  found  that  "at  the  close  of  l»3a 
rhoto  w;ls  dcferri;il  uiajntfu.uicfc  ou  ih;;  railway  propcrUes  rtmouuting  to  $238  u:illioc  bssuuutiR  a  tralli<'  a.s 
Jar^u  at  thai  of  1«37  to  be  in  prospect  "  Cf.  I.  C.  C,  ftr.jncla(  Ki<jL.ir'.mr':U;  of  iMUria'j:  til..tv;:JiLUt  No. 
3911,  Matrl.   1639 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14007 


amounted  to  some  300  million  dollars  annually  during  1926  to  1 930.^5  In  1932 
they  were  not  much  more  than  10%  of  that  amount;  in  1933  they  were  95%  below 
their  1929  level.^o  They  recovered  to  the  1929  volume  in  1937  as  a  result  of  the 
needs  of  the  increased  traffic,  which  forced  railroads  to  make  up  in  part  for  their 
previous  curtailment  in  expenditures  of  this  type. 

Reductions  in  capital  expenditures  for  roadway  and  structures  were  relatively 
moderate  when  compared  with  those  for  new  equipment.  Even  these  reductions, 
however,  were  startling  in  their  absolute  magnitude;  expenditures  fell  from  ap- 
proximately 500  million  dollars  in  the  predepression  period  to  about  100  million 
in  the  years  of  deepest  depression.  The  rise  in  1937  to  less  than  200  million 
dollars  was  likewise  much  less  spectacular  than  the  corresponding  change  in 
capital  expenditures  for  equipment. 

The  difference  in  behavior  of  the  two  classes  of  capital  expenditures  is  explained 
by  the  difference  in  the  means  of  adjustment  to  reduced  demand  for  railroad 
services.  But  utilizing  idle  stocks  of  cars,  railroads  were  able  to  eliminate  almost 
completely  their  expenditures  for  new  cars.  When  traffic  increased  as  was  the 
case  in  1936-7  and  the  idle  stock  was  depleted,  it  became  necessary  to  buy  large 
quantities  of  capital  equipment.-'  On  the  other  hand,  it  was  necessary  thj-ough- 
out  the  depression  to  make  continuous  use  of  the  entire  roadway  and  structures, 
and  expenditures  for  such  facilities  could  not  be  curtailed  as  drastically  as  expen- 
ditures for  rolling  equipment.^* 

B.    STEEL    CONSUMPTION    BT    THE    RAILROADS 

The  drastic  reductions  in  expenditures  for  maintenance  and  capital  equipment 
by  the  railroads  involved  curtailment  of  the  industry's  consumption  of  steel 
(Chart  4 — See  tables  4  and  5).  The  available  statistic?  do  not  allow  a  clean-cut 
division  between  maintenance  and  capital  expenditures  for  steel,  but  the  following 
table  on  iron  and  steel  consumption  shows  the  general  trend  and  the  fluctuations 
in  the  railroads'  total  consumption  of  finished  steel  and  also  in  the  railroads' 
"direct"  purchases  of  iron  and  steel  products. 2» 


Table  5.— Iron  and  Steel  Consumption 

by  Railroads,  192S-19S8 

Iron  and  Steel 

Products  as 

Estimated 

Iron  and  Steel 

Percent  of 

Consumption 

Products 

Total  RaU- 

of  Hot-Rolled 

Year 

Purchased ' 

road  Pur- 

Iron and  Steel 

(million.s  of 

chases  of  Fuel 

Products  > 

dollars) 

Materials 

(thousands 

and 

of  gross  tons) 

Supplies » 

1923 

$465  0 

26. 7% 
27.2 

8  424 

1924 - 

365.6 

7;  196 

1925.. 

419.3 

30.1 

7,809 

1926 

507.3 

32.5 

7,656 

1927 

432.6 

31.0 

6,232 

1928 

397.5 

31.3 

6.119 

1929 

437.8 
329.7 

32.9 
31.7 

7  28.S 

1930 

4,679 

1931.. 

202.1 

29.1 

2.710 

1932    

1,050 
1,317 

1933... 

110.7 

23.8 

1934 

139.8 

26.0 

2,271 

1935 

156.9 

26.5 

1,751 

1936 ,. 

273.8 

34.1 

3  645 

1937 

1938 

162.2 

26.1 

1,289 

Sources: 

1  Data  for  years  1923  to  1929  and  1933  to  1938  from  Association  of  American  Railroads,  Bureau  of  Railway 
Economics.  A  Review  of  Railway  Operations.  Data  for  1930  to  1932  from  "/Jaitoay /Ipe."  These  figures 
cover  "direct"  purchases  only  and  are  not  comparable  with  the  tonnage  figures  in  the  last  column. 

•  Computed  by  apportioning  individual  hot-rolled  product  totals  on  the  basis  of  Iron  Age  distribution 
reports  and  by  allocating  jobber  shipments  to  ultimate  consumers.  See  M.  W.  'Worthing,  Distribution  of 
Steel  Products  to  Major  Consuming  Industries,  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  October  30, 1939. 


»  See  Table  4  in  text. 

M  See  Table  4  in  text. 

>'  See  Appendix,  Table  16. 

>s  See  Appendix,  Table  16. 

"  "Direct"  purchases  only  cover  purchases  made  directly  by  the  roads  and  do  not  include  the  value  of 
material  and  supplies  purchased  indirectly  for  the  railways  by  contractors  who  carry  on  construction  work, 
build  equipment  and  do  other  work  for  the  railways. 


14008        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Like  railroad  revenues,  dollar  purchases  of  iron  and  steel  products  reached  their 
peak  in  1926,  fell  to  a  post-war  low  in  1932  when  purchases  were  77%  below  1929, 
and  recovered  in  1937  to  the  level  of  1930.  Even  then,  they  were  still  30% 
below  the  1926  peak.  For  the  five  years  beginning  with  1926,  purchases  averaged 
421  million  dollars,  and  for  the  five  years  1931-5  they  averaged  only  146  million 
dollars,  a  decline  of  65%.  In  tonnage  terms,  the  railroad  consumption  of  steel 
amounted  to  7800  thousand  gross  tons  in  1925,  fell  87%  to  a  low  in  1932,  and 
recovered  to  approximately  50%  of  the  1925  level  in  1936  and  1937. 

The  "direct"  purchases  of  iron  and  steel  products  decreased  more  rapidly  in 
the  depression  years,  1931  to  1933,  and  increased  more  rapidly  from  1934  to  1937 

Chart  4 


RAILROAD  STEEL  CONSUMPTION  AND  RAILROAD 
MAINTENANCE  AND  CAPITAL  EXPENDITURES 


1 

L 

» 

\ 

/ 

V 

i 

\ 

/ 

\ 

\ 

\ 

r 

ST 

NSU 

(TO 

Ea 
Mn 

INSI 

ION 

\ 

. 

\ 

i 

=»t. 

/ 

MA 
AN 
EXf 

S 

NTE 
DC 
•ENC 
DOL 

v\ 

NAr 

APIT 
ITU 

AL 
RES 

\ 

1 

J 

vl 

\ 

\ 

\ 

i 

/ 

/ 

\ 

9 
8 

6       2 

s    i 

4       <2 


o>  o  ^  <y»  G^  o^  <y^  o\  ffi 


Scum,   fmn  Agt,  Airwtican  tion  and  5te«/  inOAute,  jnrf  Astocittion  ol  AmttKan  RsJfoaJi 


than  total  purchases  of  fuel,  materials  and  supplies.  These  differences  in  rate 
of  fluctuation  are  partly  attributable  to  the  fact  that  these  iron  and  steel  prod- 
ucts are  durable  goods  and  their  purchases  can  be  more  easily  postponed  than 
such  items  as  fuel,  which  must  bear  a  direct  relation  to  traffic.  The  Interstate 
Commerce  Commission  found  that,  in  part  as  a  result  of  such  deferability,  one- 
fourth  of  the  total  undermaintenance  in  1938  consisted  in  lack  of  rail  renewals.^" 
Full  renewals  could  have  meant  increased  expenditures  on  rails  of  43  million 
dollars,  if  there  were  a  return  to  the  1937  traffic,  which  was  still  approximatelv 
20%,  below  the  traffic  level  of  1929.3' 


2'  Expenditures  on  heavier  rails  reached  a  peak  of  $47.2  million  in  1928,  fell  75%  to  a  depression  low  o  f 
$12.0  million  in  1932  and  recovered  to  $31.8  million  in  1936.  In  general,  rail  purchases  from  1923  to  1930 
averaged  $40.0  million  per  year  but  fell  40%  to  an  average  of  $23.1  million  from  1931  through  1937  (Report  of 
the  Carriers  to  the  Bureau  of  Railway  Economics). 

3'  Cf.  I.  C.  C,  Financial  Requirements  of  Railways,  Statement  No.  3911,  (March,  1939). 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14009 


C.    THE  INFLUENCE  OF  THE  PRICE  OF  STEEL  ON  ITS  CONSUMPTION  BY  THE  RAILROAD 
INDUSTRY 

It  has  been  shown  that  fluctuations  in  steel  consumption  are  closely  related  to 
the  volume  of  railroad  services,  to  business  fluctuations  and  to  the  financial  con- 
dition of  the  railroads.  In  a  setting  of  these  basic  factors,  what  role  can  the 
price  of  steel  play  in  its  consumption  by  the  railroads? 

Some  understanding  of  the  effect  of  changes  in  the  price  of  steel  on  the  railroads' 
consumption  of  steel  can  be  had  from  Table  6  and  Charts  5  and  6.  Table  6 
shows  railroad  expenditures  for  equipment  and  ways  and  structures  in  terms  of 
1929  dollars.  The  figures  in  this  table  were  computed  by  dividing  the  actual 
expenditures  given  in  Table  4  by  the  appropriate  railroad  price  indices  for  equip- 
ment and  road  construction.^^  This  result  is  a  quantity  index  which  shows 
physical  volume  of  investments  measured  in  terms  of  1929  dollars,  rather  than 
the  sums  of  money  expended  from  year  to  year.  If  there  were  marked  influences 
of  steel  prices  on  the  quantity  of  steel  included  in  the  total  physical  volume  of 
investment  and  therefore  on  total  investment,  rising  quantities  of  total  invest- 
ments would  tend  to  be  associated  with  decreasing  steel  prices. 


Table 


-Railroad  Expenditures  at  1929  Prices,  1923-1935 
[Millions  of  1929  dollars] 


Year 

Equipment  Expenditures 

Ways  and  Structure  Expendi- 
tures 

Total 
Mainte- 
nance 
Expend- 
itures 

Total 
Capital 
Expend- 
itures 

Grand 

Mainte- 
nance 

Capital 

Total 

Mainte- 
nance 

Capital 

Total 

Total 

1923 

1924 

1925- 

1926. 

1927 _- 

1928. 

1929 

1930 

1931 

1932 

1933- 

1934 

1935 

$1,376 

1,288 

1,355 

1,372 

1,239 

1,248 

1,203 

1,024 

894 

752 

727 

702 

704 

$640 
505 
364 
398 
293 
240 
321 
330 
80 
44 
19 
101 
82 

$2,016 

1,793 

1,719 

1,770 

1,532 

1,488 

1,524 

1,354 

974 

796 

746 

803 

786 

$761 
742 
787 
835 
847 
833 
855 
743 
594 
429 
406 
446 
481 

$353 
357 
395 
494 
471 
450 
532 
573 
323 
160 
112 
147 
133 

$1, 114 

1,099 

1,182 

1,329 

1,318 

1,283 

1,387 

1,316 

917 

589 

518 

593 

614 

$2, 137 
2,030 
2,142 
2,207 
2,086 
2,081 
2,058 
1,767 
1,488 
1,181 
1,133 
1,148 
1,185 

$993 

f& 

892 
764 
690 
853 
903 
403 
204 
131 
248 
215 

$3,130 
2,892 
2,901 
3,099 
2,850 
2,771 
2,911 
2,670 
1,891 
1,385 
1,264 
1,396 
1,400 

Source:  Derived  from  Table  4  in  text  and  from  price  indexes  in  S.  Fabricant,  Capital  Consumption  and 
Adjustment,  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research,  1938,  pp.  178-179. 

Chart  5  compares  percentage  changes  in  composite  steel  prices  with  percent- 
age changes  in  various  types  of  physical  investments  of  railroads.  In  Chart  5d 
the  physical  volume  arising  from  maintenance  expenditures  is  evidently  without 
any  gross  relation  to  price  changes.  In  the  case  of.  total  volume  of  physical  invest- 
ments, rising  prices,  as  shown  in  Chart  oa  are  associated  with  slightly  rising 
volumes.  The  same  is  true  for  the  other  two  components,  the  volume  of  total 
way  and  structure  expenditures  (Chart  5c)  and  total  equipment  expenditures 
(Chart  5b).  Chart  5e  shows  unmistakably,  with  respect  to  the  physical  volume 
of  capital  expenditures,  that  the  more  steel  prices  rose,  in  comparison  to  the  pre- 
ceding period,  the  greater  increases  there  were  in  the  physical  investment  of  the 
railroads,  and'  thus  in  the  quantity  of  steel  consumed  by  the  railroads.  If  any- 
thing, these  charts  show,  as  a  whole,  that  decreasing  steel  prices  have  not  been 
associated  historically  with  rising  quantities  of  physical  investments.^^ 

A  more  direct  analysis  of  the  relation  between  steel  prices  and  steel  consumption 
by  the  railroads  is  shown  in  Cliart  6  (based  on  Table  5  and  Appendix  Table  17). 
This  chart  compares  annual  changes  in  steel  consumption  by  the  railroads  with 
changes  i^  the  composite  steel  price,  which  was  used  in  the  absence  of  an  accurate 
average  price  per  ton  for  railroad  steel.^^  If  the  annual  purchases  of  steel  by  the 
railroads  were  primarily  influenced  by  changes  in  steel  prices,  a  general  correlation 
between  greater  purchases  and  lowered  prices  should  be  evidenced.     Chart  6 

3!  Taken  from  S.  Fabricant,  Capital  Consumption  and  Adjustment,  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research 
1938,  pp.  178-179. 

"  See  appendix.  Table  17. 

'•  It  should  be  noted  that  the  data  with  respect  to  railroad  steel  consumption  are  subject  to  some  inaccu- 
racies, and  that  the  changes  in  the  average  price  per  ton  of  railroad  steel  may  differ  somewhat  from  the  changes 
in  the  composite  steel  price. 


14010       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

fails  to  show  such  a  relationship  and  warrants  the  inference  that  other  factors  of 
much  greater  importance  than  price  influence  the  quantities  of  railroad  steel 
purchases. 

The  foregoing  analysis  supports  the  vie>v  that  price  considerations  play  rather 
subordinate  roles  among  the  factors  which  determine  the  voUime  of  steel  purchases 
in  the  tailroad  industry,  as  well  as  total  steel  consumption  by  the  railroads.     Steel 

Chart  5 


H_    120 

z 

o 

cc    100 

UJ 

a. 
z 
^     80 

z 

UJ 

i     60 

i  «> 

^   120 

X 

9  100 

i 

1-80 
60 


RELATION  OF  STEEL  PRICES 
TO  RAILROAD  PHYSICAL  INVESTMENTS 

1924  - 1935 


100 
80 
60 
40 

fa) 

I9ii 

1526 

1929 

1934 

1924 
930*1. 

27  19*3 

1935 

1931 

^193. 

TO 

AL 

(d) 

1925 

1925 
1928* 

193S 

.934 

1924  1< 
19*30 

bl933 
•  1931 

1929 

1932 

MAINTENANCE 

80     § 


(b) 

192S 

.929 

1934 

925* 
1924^ 

"°192 

1928. 
1933* 
^    ,932 

1935 

'.93. 

EQUIF 

WENT 

(C) 

1925 
1924 

1926» 
1927 

1929 
•  1935 

19-34 

1930 

1928 

• 

1933 

1931 

•  1932 

VAYS 

AND 

ITRUC 

rURES 

,934 

CAf 

TAL 

T 

1930 

• 

1926* 

1924 

I92S 
1927 

•  1935 

,933 

1931 

1^ 

• 

85      90 


95      100     105     110  115  85    90      95     100    105 
STEEL  PRICES  IN  PER  CENT  OF  PREVIOUS  YEAR 


no 


40 
115 


Source:  Iron  Aoe,  Aisocatlon  of  American  Railroads  and  Interstate  Commerce  Gynmlsshn 


for  maintenance  is  dependent  to  a  high  degree  upon  technical  factors  and  to  that 
extent  the  volume  of  traffic  dictates  quantities  required.  Capital  expenditures 
for  steel,  on  the  other  hand,  appear  to  be  dominated  by  such  factors  as  availability 
of  sufficient  funds  and  the  necessity  of  making  replacements  and  improvements 
which  were  postponed  during  the  depression.  When  necessitated  by  increased 
demand  for  transportation,  capital  expenditures  are  likely  to  be  made  at  a  rapid 
rate.     Thus,  general  business  conditions  seem  to  determine  the  timing  and  extent 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14011 


of  those  expenditures,  which  rise  rapidly  in  a  boom  in  spite  of  rising  steel  prices 
and  shrink  during  the  depression  to  an  unimportant  fraction  of  their  former  level 
irrespective  of  steel  price  decreases. 

The  comparative  inefifectiveness  of  a  reduction  in  steel  prices  to  increase  the 
consumption  of  railroad  steel  «an  be  further  demonstrated  by  a  comparison  of  the 
total  cost  of  steel  purchases  with  total  railroad  revenues.  Ultimately  the  cost  of 
steel  purchases  is  reflected  in  the  cost  to  the  consumer  of  railroad  services.  A 
comparison  of  railroad  revenues  (here  assumed  to  represent  the  cost  to  the  con- 
sumer of  railroad  services)  with  estimated  total  expenditures  for  railroad  ateel, 
during  the  period  from  1923  to  1938  ^^  shows  that  for  the  sixteen-year  period 
expenditures  for  steel  averaged  about  5%  of  railroad  revenues.  If  a  reduction  of 
10%  were  made  in  the  price  of  railroad  steel  and  if  this  reduction  were  passed 
on  in  the  form  of  a  rate  reductidn,  it  would  constitute  a  reduction  of  approxi- 
mately one-half  of  one  per  cent  in  the  cost  to  the  consumer  of  railroad  services. 
As  shown  elsewhere  herein,  the  increase  in  the  volume  of  railroad  services  as  a 
result  of  rate  reduction  is  low.     (The  elasticity  of  demand  in  the  case  of  passenger 

Chabt  6 


5-    220 


£     120 


52     100 


RELATION  OF  RAILROAD  STEEL  CONSUMPTION 
TO  COMPOSITE  STEEL  PRICE 

1924  - 1938 


•  1936 

1934* 

1933, 

"^=- 

\nf 

1937* 

»».    .1927     " 

6 

,1930 

-.93, 

193l' 

1932 

1938* 

90  100  110 

STEEL  PRICE  IN  PER  CENT  OF  PREVIOUS  YEAR 


180 
160 


220 


120 


Souirt.  /ran  Age  an)  Aintrian  Inn  ml  StttI  InsCtute 


tr^fl5c  was  found  to  be  approximately  one  half.*»).  Hence  a  10%  reduction  in 
steel  prices,  if  passed  on  to  the  consumer  of  railroad  services,  would  serve  to 
increase  the  total  services  rendered  by  railroads  only  slightly  and  to  increase  the 
steel  consumed  by  the  railroads  probably  by  less  than  1%.  In  addition,  trans- 
poration  rates  are  more  or  less  inflexible  due  to  the  institutional  method  by  which 
they  are  set  up,  and  any  changes  in  the  cost  of  steel  purchases,which  is  "a  small 
part  of  total  railroad  costs,  could  hardly  be  expected  to  be  passed  on  in  the  form 
of  lower  rates  in  the  short  run. 

The  inability  of  steel  producers  to  increase  railroad  consumption  of  steel 
substantially  by  a  price  reduction  is  apparent;  and  consequently,  reductions  in 
steel  prices  by  themselves  could  be  expected  to  have  little  effect  on  railroad  rates, 
on  total  volume  of  railroad  services,  and  on  total  steel  consumption  by  the 
railroads. 


"  The  average  computed  here  is  only  a  rough  approxiraation,  for  there  are  definite  limitations  in  the  stee' 
expenditures  data  -ised.  The  figures  were  computed  by  multiplying  estimates  of  railroad  steel  consumption 
(which  are  subject  to  some  inaccuracies)  by  the  ;omposite  steel  price  index  in  lieu  of  an  average  price  per  ton 
for  railroad  steel.  Even  if  the  average  price  of  railroad  steel  were  slightly  in  excess  of  the  composite  steel 
price  index,  It  would  not,  however,  materially  change  thetesults. 

»«  See:  Supra,  p.  6,  and  National  Resources  Committee,  op.  cit.,  pp.  90,  91  and  99. 

124491 — 41— pt.  26 28 


i4ai2 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


VI.  Summary 

Steel  costs  form  only  a  small  proportion  of  the  total  costs  of  transportation, 
and  a  change  in  steel  prices  could  have  practically  no  effect  in  increasing  rail 
transportation  by  reducing  its  cost  to  the  ultimate  consumer.  Consumers' 
income,  industrial  production  and  competition  from  other  transportation  media 
have  been  the  important  factors  influencing  the  volume  of  railroad  services  and 
the  consequent  consumption  of  steel  by  the  railroads.  The  demand  for  steel  by 
the  railroads  is  inelastic;  a  given  percentage  price  reduction  will  not  induce  as 
large  a  percentage  increase  in  the  consumption  of  steel.  The  low  consumption 
of  steel  by  the  railway  industry  in  the  last  decade  has  been  due  to  the  declining 
trend  in  the  demand  for  rail  transportation,  to  the  severe  depression  in  business, 
and  to  the  financial  difficulties  prising  therefrom.  No  conceivable  reduction  in 
steel  prices  could  have  significantly  altered  the  conditions  arising  from  these  forces. 

Appendix 


Table  7. — Estimated  Consumption  of  Hot-Rolled  Steel  by  the  Railroads,  1928-1938 


Year 

Consumption 
(thousands  of 
gross  tons) 

Percent  of 
Total  Con- 
sumption by 
All  Industries 

Year 

Consumption 
(thousands  of 
gross  tons) 

Percent  of 
Total  Con- 
sumption by 
All  Industries 

1923 

8,424 
7,196 
7,809 
7,656 
6,232 
6,119 

41679 

25. 3% 

25.6 

23.4 

21.6 

19.0 

16.3 

17.7 

15.9 

1931 

2,710 
1,050 
1,317 
2,271 
1,751 
3,645 
('•,184 
289 

14  1% 

1924 

1932 

10  0 

1925 

1933 

7  9 

1926 

1934 

12  0 

1927 

1935 

7  3 

1928 

1936 

10.8 

1929 

1937 

11.4 

1930 

1938 

6. 1 

Source:  Computed  by  apportioning  individual  hot-rolled  product  totals  on  the  basis  of  Iron  Age  distri- 
bution reports  and  by  allocating,  jobber  shipments  to  ultimate  consumers.  See  M.  W.  Worthing,  Distri- 
btUion  of  Steel  Products  to  Major  Consuming  Industries,  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  October  30,  1939. 

Table  8.— Freight  Traffic,  1921-1938 


Revenue  Ton-Miles 

Year 

Revenue  Ton-Miles 

Year 

All  roads 
(miUions) 

Class  I  roads 
(millions) 

All  roads 
(miUions) 

Class  I  roads 
(millions) 

1921 - 

309,533' 

342. 188 
416,  256 
391,945 
417,418 
447,444 
432,014 
436,087 

450. 189 

306,840 
339,285 
412, 727 
388.  415 
413,814 
443,  746 
428, 737 
432,915 
447,  322 

1930 

385,815 
311,073 
235,309 
250,651 
270,  292 
283,637 
341, 182 
362,815 
1  313. 109 

383,450 

1922 

1931 - 

309.225 

1923 -  .  . 

1932 - 

233, 977 

1924 ..^c...  . 

249, 223 

1925.... 

1934 

268,711 

1926.. 

1935 

1936 

282, 037 

1927 

339  246 

1928 

1937 

360  620 

1929 

1938 

290,154 

'  Year  ended  June  30,  1938.    Other  figures  are  for  the  calendar  year. 
Source :  From  Reports  of  Interstate  Commerce  Commission. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14013 


Table  9. 


-Indexes  of  Industrial  Production  and  Freight  Car  Loadings,  1921-1938, 
Monthly  Averages  {1923-1925  =  100) 


Industrial 
Produc- 
tion ' 

Freight  Car  Loadings » 

Year 

Industrial 

Freight  Car  Loadings ' 

Year 

Miscella- 
neous 

Merchan- 
dise (1.  c.  1.) 

Produc- 
tion! 

Miscella- 
neous 

Merchan- 
dise a  c.  1.) 

1921 

67 
85 
101 
95 
104 
108 
106 

72 
84 
97 
97 
106 
109 
108 
111 

lis 

87 
94 

99 
105 
105 
105 
104 
105 

1930 

96 
81 
64 
76 
79 
90 
105 
110 
86 

99 
78 
55 
58 
64 
69 
82 
86 
67 

97 

1923 

1932 

1933 

72 

1934 

1935 

1926  „ 

1927  .... 

1928    .     -. 

1937 

67 

1929.  ... 

Sources:  Monthly  data  of  these  figures  (as  used  in  Chart  1)  are  found  in  Reports  of  the  Division  of  Re- 
search and  Statistics  of  the  Board  of  Governors  of  the  Federal  Reserve  Board. 

1  Released  by  Board  of  Governors  of  the  Federal  Reserve  System,  Division  of  Research  and  Statistics. 

2  Federal  Reserve  Bulletin,  June,  1937,  pp.  624-527,  and  current  numbers. 

Table  10. — Passenger  Miles,  Consumers'  Income,  and  Population,  1920-1937 


Revenue 
Passenger 

Miles 
(billions) 

Consumers'  Income 

Midyear  Es- 

Year 

(Billions 
of  current 
dollars) 

(Billions 
of  1936 
doUars) 

timates  of 
Population 
(miUions) 

1920 

46.8 
37.3 
35.5 
38.  < 
36.1 
35.9 
35.5 
33.6 
31.6 
31.1 
26.8 
21.9 
17.0 
16.3 
18.0 
18.5 
22.4 
24.7 

$66.8 
53.9 
57.9 
66.5 
67.3 
70.9 
73.3 
73.2 
75.8 
79.3 
71.9 
59.4 
45.9 
44.6 
51.8 
55.9 
63.9 
70.0 

$47.0 
42.3 
48.8 
54.8 
55.4 
57.0 
58.-3 
58.9 
62.2 
65.3 
60.4 
54.6 
46.7 
48.2 
54.0 
56.9 
63.9 

106.5 

1921 

108.2 

1922 

109,9 

1923 

111.5 

1924 

•       113.2 

1925 

114.9 

1926 

116.5 

1927 

118.2 

1928 -.- , 

119.9 

1929 

121.5 

123.1 

1931                           - 

124.1 

1932             

125.0 

1933        : 

125.8 

1934 

126.6 

1935-. ...--1 

127.5 

1936 

128.3 

1937 

129.3 

Source:  Report  of  Industial  Committee  to  National  Resources  Committee,  Patterns  of  Resource  Use 
(1939). 


Table  11. — Registrations  of  Passenger  Automobiles, 

1921-1938 

Year 

Number 
(thousands 
omitted) 

Index 
(1921  =  100) 

Year 

Number 
(thousands 
omitted) 

Index 
(1921  =  100) 

1921.  .              

9346 
■  10863 
13480 
15461 
17496 
19237 
20219 
21379 
23122 

100.0 
116.2 
144.2 
165.4 
187.2 
205.8 
216.3 
228.8 
247.4 

1930 ....... 

23059 
22366 

20644 
21532 
22563 
24178 
25450 
25262 

246.7 

1922               

1931 :.. 

239.3 

1923     .               .... 

1932 

223.5 

1924 

1933 

220.9 

1925 

1934 

230.4 

1926 

1935 

241.4 

1927 

1936 

258.7 

1928 

1937 

272.3 

1929 

1938 

270.3 

boorce:  Automobile  Facts  and  Figures,  1939,  p.  16. 


i4ai4 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Table  12. — Total  Operating  Revenues,  Total  Operating  Expenses,  Taxes,  and  Net 
Railway  Operating  Income,  1921-1938  (Class  I  Railroads) 


Total 
Operating 


(thousands 
of  dollars) 


Total  Operating 


%  of  total 
revenues 


Amount 
(thousands 
of  dollars) 


Net  Railway  Operat- 
ing Income 


Amount 
(thousands 
of  dollars) 


1921. 
1922 
1923 
1924 
1925. 
1926 
1927. 
1928. 
1929. 
1930. 
1931. 
1932. 
1933. 
1934. 
1935. 
1936. 
1937. 


$5,516,598 

5,  559, 093 
&,289, 580 
fi,'921,  496 
6, 122,  510 
6, 382,  940 
6, 136, 300 

6,  111,  736 
6, 279, 621 
5,  281, 197 
4, 188.  343 
3, 126,  760 
3,  095,  404 
3, 271, 587 
3,451,929 
4, 052, 734 
4, 166, 069 
3,  565, 000 


$4, 562, 668 
4,  414,  522 
4,  895, 167 
4,  507,  885 
4,  536,  880 
4,669,337 
4, 574, 178 
4, 427,  995 
4,  506,  056 
3,  930,  929 
3,  223,  575 
2,  403,  445 
2,  249, 232 
2,441,823 
2,  592,  741 
2,931,425 
3, 119, 065 
2,722,000 


82.71% 

79.41 

77.83 

76.13 

74.10 

73.16 

74.54 

72.45 

71.76 

74.43 

76.97 

76.87 

72.66 

74.64 

75.11 

72.33 

74.87 

76.35 


$275, 876 
301, 035 
331,916 
340, 337 
358,  »16 
388, 923 
376, 110 
389,432 
398,683 
348, 554 
303,628 
275. 135 
249,623 
239, 625 
236, 946 
319, 753 
325, 665 
341,000 


$600,937 

760, 187 

961, 955 

973, 937 

1,121,076 

1,  213,  090 

1, 067, 985 

1, 172, 864 

1,  251,  698 

868,879 

525,628 

326,  398 

474,  296 

462, 652 

499,  819 

667, 347 

690,  204 

372, 846 


10.9% 

13.7 

15  3 

10.4 

18.3 

19.0 

17.4 

19.2 

19.9 

16.5 

12.5 

10.4 

15.3 

14.1 

14.5 

16.5 

14.2 

10.5 


Sources:  Report  of  Committee  Appointed  September  tO, 
Recommendations  Upon  the  General  Transpo) 
Reports  of  Interstate  Commerce  Commission 


J  the  President  of  the  United  States  to  Submit 
Recommendations  Uponthe  General  Transportation  Situation  (19SS),  Table  12,  p.  78.  Based  on 
sion. 

'  1938  figures  from  Association  of  American  Railroads,  Bureau  of  Railway  Economics,  A  Review  of  Rail- 
way Operations  in  19S8. 

Table  13. — Average  Hourly  Earnings,  Average  Dividend  Rates  on  Capital  Stock 
Outstanding,  and  Interest  on  Debt,  1929-1937  (Class  I  Railroads) 


Year 

Average 
Hourly 

Earnings  > 
(cents) 

Average  Dv- 

idend  Rates' 

(percent) 

Interest  on 
Debt* 

(millions  of 
dollars) 

1929 

66.6(S 
67.8 
68.9 
63.6 
62.9 
63.6 

69!  1 
70.9 

5.99% 

6.01 

3.99 

1.12 

1.16 

1.64 
2.11 
2.07 

511 

1930 

609 

1931 

618 

1932 

625 

1933 

524 

1934 

1935 

611 

1037.... 

'  Committee  of  Public  Relations  of  the  Eastern  Railroads,  A  Yearbook  of  Railroad  Information  (1935  and 
1938  editions),  p.  62. 

'  Quoted  in  Report  of  the  Emergency  Board  to  the  President,  (1938),  p.  9.  The  capital  stock  outstanding 
Includes  stock  of  railroads  In  trusteeship  or  receivership.  Also  based  on  data  from  Statistics  of  Railways 
in  the  United  States,  Interstate  Commerce  Commerce,  1937. 

«  Committee  of  Public  Relations  of  the  Eastern  Railroads,  op.  cit.,  p.  38. 


„  -        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        14015 

Table  14. — Maintenance  Expenditures  and  Revenue  Ton-Miles,  1921-1938  (Class 
I  Railroads) 


Mainteuance  Expendi- 
tures 

Ton-Miles  of 
Revenue 
Freight 
(millions) 

Year 

Maintenance  Expendi- 
tures 

Ton-MUes  of 
Revenue 
Freight 
(millions) 

Year 

(millions 
of  dollars) 

Index  Av- 
erage 1921- 
1928=100 

(mUlions 
of  dollars) 

Index  Av- 
erage 1921- 
1928=100 

1921 

1922 

$2,008 
1,981 
2,279 
2,053 
2,076 
2,150 
2,088 
2,' 005 
2,058 

96.6 
95.3 
109.6 
98.7 
99.8 
103.4 
100.4 
96.4 
99.0 

306, 840 
339, 286 
412,  727 
388,415 
413,814 
443,  746 
428,  737 
432, 915 
447,322 

1930 

1931 

1932 

1,725 
1,348 
970 
921 
1,003 
1,076 
1,238 
1,322 
1,097 

82.9 
64.8 
46.6 
44.3 
48.2 
61.7 
69.5 
63.6 
62.8 

383,  460 
309, 225 

1924 

1925 

1926 

1927 

1928  - 

1929 

1933 

1934. 

1935 

1936 

1937... 

1938 

249, 223 
268,711 
282, 037 
339,  246 
360,620 
290,164 

Source:  Association  of  American  Railroads,  Bureau  of  Railway  Economics.   A  Review  of  Railway  Opera 
tions  in  1938  (p.  20),  and  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  Statistics  of  Railways  in  the  United  States 


Table  15. 


-Railroad  Equipment  Expenditures,  Available  Freight  Cars,  and  Car- 
loadings,  1921-19SS 


Year 

Average 

Freight 

Cars  Owned 

(thousands) 

Average 
Service- 
able Cars 
(thousands) 

Surplus  Cars 

Lowest 

Reported 

(thousands) 

Carloadings 
(thousands) 

Equipment 

Expenditure 

(mUlions 

of  dollars) 

1921 

2,317 
2,304 
2,303 
2,331 
2,365 
2,345 
2,329 
2  298 
2,267 
2,270 
2,229 
2,160 
2,072 
1,969 
1,863 
1,770 
1,723 
1,713 

1% 

2,113 
2,146 
2,168 
2,190 
2,191 
2,164 
2,132 
2,128 
2,053 
1,922 
1,779 
1,674 
1,584 
1,526 
1,643 
1,496 

80 
4 

14 

99 
112 

81 
135 
104 
119 
393 
636 
545 

318 
208 
112 
104 
139 

966 

1,000 

1,098 

1,113 

1,124 

1,209 

1,129 

1,197 

1,  202 

085 

776 

651 

687 

646 

734 

826 

847 

726 

311 

1922 

246 

1923 

682 

1924     .                        .             .  - 

494 

338 

1926 

372 

1927.. 

289 

1928 ...... 

224 

1929 

321 

1930 

328 

1931. 

73 

36 

1933 

16 

1934 

92 

1936 

79 

1936 

169 

1937 

323 

1938-   . 

115 

Source:  Taken  from  testimony  of  Dr.  Lauchlin  Currie  before  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Com- 
mittee on  May  16,  1939,  Volume  3,  Table  IV,  p.  357.    For  note^  and  methods  see  Dr.  Currie's  appendix. 


14016       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  l&.— Freight  and  Passenger  Miles,  Mileage  Operated,  Equipment  in  Service, 
and  Installalion  of  Equipment  and  Rails  of  Class  I  Railways,  1926-1937 


1? 

s 

o 

Equipment     in 
Service,    End   of 
Year 

Rails  Laid  in  Replace- 
ment   (thousands  of 
gross  tons) 

New    Equipment 
InstaUed  a 

^R 

•£S 

1% 

Year 

f 

ai 

sf 

II 

til 

_ 

•a 

S 

c 

1 
SO 

2 

1 

1 

c 

ti 

11 

fe 

p-l 

^ 

p^ 

Ph 

t- 

^ 

CO 

« 

ft. 

1926 

486 

35.5 

394. 9 

62  8 

2,349 

54.8 

3,818 

2,210 

1,608 

472 
474 

33.6 
31.6 

399.2 
403.5 

61.4 
59  5 

2,325 
2,298 

53.8 
53.  1 

3,819 
3,806 

2,125 
2,080 

1,690 
1,725 

1928 

1929 

490 

31.1 

406.5 

57  5 

2,277 

52.3 

3,610 

1,958 

1,652 

1930    

4^0 

26.8 

408.0 

56.5 

2,277 

52.1 

2,764 

1,517 

1,157 

1931 

338 

21.9 

408.2 

55.1 

2,201 

50.7 

1,715 

985 

730 

1932 

257 

17.0 

407.1 

53.  2 

2,145 

49.4 

798 

395 

403 

90 

2,815 

58 

1933 

273 

16.3 

404.9 

50.8 

2,035 

46.5 

403 

459 

14 

1,936 

7 

1934 - 

•296 

18.0 

402.4 

48.2 

1,  938 

43.8 

1,165 

631 

534 

90 

23, 948 

270 

1935 

310 

18.5 

400.3 

46.5 

1,836 

41.6 

1,159 

583 

576 

139 

6,987 

225 

1936 

372 

22.4 

397.8 

45.0 

1,758 

40.6 

1,701 

921 

780 

98 

37,  554 

159 

1937 

395 

24.7 

395.6 

44.4 

1,744 

40.3 

1,975 

1,030 

945 

441 

69,118 

576 

Source:  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  Statistics  of  Railways,  1937,  and  earlier  volumes. 

'  Total  of  revenue  and  non-revenue  ton  miles. 

'  Total  of  steam  and  electric  locomotives. 

5  Data  prior  to  1932  not  available.  Data  for  domestic  shipments  of  locomotives  (U.  S.  Bureau  of  the 
Census)  and  freight  and  passenger  cars  (American  Railway  Car  Institute)  indicate  the  following  changes 
between  1929  and  1937;  locomotives,  — 36.5<j;,  freight  train  cars,  — 10.97ci  and  passenger  train  cars,  —57.6%. 
See:  Survey  of  Current  Business,  1938  Supplement,  p.  162. 

Table  17.— Composite  Price  of  Finished  Steel,  1923-1988 


Composite 

Steel  Price 

(cents  per 

pound) 

2.697 


1924 ■....  2.505 

1925 2.334 

1926 - 2.315 


Source:  Iron  Age  (January  5,  1939),  p.  198. 


1932. 
1933- 
1934. 


Composite 

Steel  Price 

{cents  per 

pound) 

1.957 

1.901 

1.879 

2.033 

_  2.058 

2.077 

2.464 

2.394 


Exhibit  No.  1415 

AN  ANALYSIS  OF  THE  DEMAND  FOR  STEEL   IN  THE   CONTAINER 
INDUSTRY 

This  is  an  analysis  prepared  by  the  Special  Economic  Research  Section  of 
United  States  Steel  Corporation,  composed  of  Messrs.  Edward  T.  Dickinson, 
Jr.,  Ernest  M.  Doblin,  H.  Gregg  Lewis,  Jacob  L.  Mosak,  Mandal  R.  Segal, 
Dwight  B.  Yntema  and  Miss  Marion  W.  Worthing.  The  work  of  this  group 
was  under  the  supervision  of  Theodore  O.  Yntema,  Professor  of  Statistics,  Uni- 
versity of  Chicago.  This  analysis  was  written  by  Mandal  R.  Segal  who  had  the 
b'^nefit  of  suggestions  from  other  melnbers  of  the  staff.  It  is  issued  by  United 
States  Steel  Corporation. 

November  1,  1939. 

CONTENT.? 
I.  Purpose. 
II.  Findings. 

III.  The  Container  Industry. 

IV.  Steel  Consumption  by  the  Container  Industry. 
V.  Relation  of  Price  to  Demand  tor  Tin  Plate: 

A.  Demand  for  Food  or  Packer  Cans. 

B.  Demand  for  Oencral  Line  Cans: 

(1)  Beer  Cans. 

(2)  Lubricant  Oil  Cans. 

(3)  Paint  and  Varnish  CanS. 

(4)  Other  General  Line  Cans. 

C.  Quantity  of  Tin  Plate  per  Can. 
VI.  Summary. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14017 

I.    Purpose 

The  purpose  of  this  study  is  to  analyze  the  factors  determining  the  quantity 
of  steel  consumed  by  the  container  industry  '  (of  which  tin  can  manufacture  is 
the  greater  part)  and  particularly  to  determine  the  importance  of  price  as  a 
factor  in  this  consumption. 

Steel  (mainly  in  the  form  of  tin  plate)  is  the  principal  raw  material  in  the 
production  of  tin  cans,  which  are  used  mainly  to  pack  consumers'  goods,  such  as 
food,  oil,  beer,  and  paints  and  varnishes.  Thus,  the  consumption  of  steel  by 
the  tin  container  industry  depends  upon: 

(1)  The  output  and  consumption  of  all  "canned"  goods,  i.  e.,  all  goods  that 
are  put  in  containers; 

(2)  The  proportion  of  this  output  that  is  put  in  tin  cans  and  not  in  containers 
made  of  other  materials;  and 

(3)  The  amount  of  steel  used  in  the  individual  container. 

A  change  in  the  price  of  steel  can  affect  steel  consumption  by  the  tin  container 
manufacturing  industry  only  in  so  far  as  it  affects  these  three  factors. 

II.    Findings 

(1)  The  demand  for  products  packed  in  tin  cans  is  dependent  primarily  upon 
consumer  income. 

(2)  There  has  been  an  upward  trend  in  tin  can  consumption,  which  is  explained 
by  the  increasing  use  of  tin  can§  to  pack  new  food  and  other  products.  This 
adaptation  of  tin  cans  to  additional  uses  in  the  past  ten  years  has  also  contributed 
to  the  relative  cyclical  stability  of  tin  can  consumption. 

(3)  Public  tastes  and  preferences  have  been  among  the  most  important  factors 
limiting  the  substitution  of  tin  cans  for  other  containers.  The  physical  and 
chemical  characteristics  of  the  products  to  be  packed  have  also  tended  to  restrict 
substitution  and  adaptation  of  tin  cans  to  new  uses.  Existing  equipment  and 
distribution  facilities  constitute  another  deterrent  to  substitution. 

(4)  Other  investigations  have  shown  that  the  demand  for  food  is  generally 
inelastic.  The  available  data  also  indicate  that  fluctuations  in  the  total  consump- 
tion of  canned  food  products  have  had  little  net  relation  to  fluctuations  in  canned 
food  prices  or  to  fluctuations  in  the  ratio  of  canned  food  prices  to  other  food 
prices.  From  these  facts  it  seems  reasonable  to  infer  that  the  demand  for 
canned  food  has  a  low  elasticity. 

(5)  The  price  of  tin  plate  is  about  one-tenth  of  the  retail  price  of  representative 
food  products  packed  in  tin  containers  and  is  probably  less  than  one-tenth  of  the 
retail  price  of  most  products  packed  in  general  line  cans.  A  10  percent  reduction 
in  the  price  of  tin  plate,  if  entirely  passed  on  to  the  consumer  of  the  canned 
product,  would  therefore  reduce  the  retail  price  of  the  canned  product  only  about 
1  percent.  In  the  case  of  canned  food  products,  this  would  result  in  a  saving 
to  the  consumer  of  only  a  small  fraction  of  one  cent  per  can.  Consequently,  any 
reduction  in  the  price  of  tin  plate,  even  if  the  consumer  of  the  canned  commodity 
received  the  full  benefit  of  such  price  reduction,  could  affect  the  final  price  of  the 
canned  commodity  only  slightly  and  could  have  no  appreciable  effect  on  the  con- 
sumption of  canned  goods. 

(6)  In  the  past  there  has  been  no  discernible  relation  between  the  consumption 
of  representative  individual  canned  food  products  and  the  price  of  tin  plate.  This 
simply  reflects  the  major  importance  of  other  factors  and  the  very  minor  impor- 
tance of  the  price  of  tin  plate  in  determining  the  consumption  of  canned  foods. 

(7)  Physical  and  chemical  requirements  of  the.products  to  be  packed  determine 
almost  entirely  the  weight,  composition  and  amount  of  the  steel  used  in  tin 
containers. 

These  findings  show  that  tin  plate  prices  have  only  a  negligible  effect  on  the 
immediate  factors  determining  steel  consumption  by  +he  container  industry, 
namely: 

(a)  the  output  and  consumption  of  all  "canned"  goods; 

(b)  the  proportion  of  this  output  that  is  put  in  tin  cans  and  not  in  other  types 
of  containers;  and 

(c)  the  amount  of  steel  used  in  the  individual  container. 

To  sum  up,  the  consumption  of  steel  by  the  container  industry  is  derived 
from  and  dependent  upon  the  consumption  of  the  products  packed  in  tin  con- 
tainers.    A  change  in  the  price  of  tin  plate  can  increase  its  consumption  only  by 

1  Although  the  container  industry  might  be'defined  as  comprising  all  types  of  containers,  including  many 
made  of  materials  other  than  steel,  this  study  is  limited  to  "lightcontainers"  made  from  light  steel  products, 
and  is  devoted  primarily  to  tin  cans,  in  the  manufacture  of-which  roughly  three--qaarters  or  more  of  the 
steel  taken  by  the  container  industry  is  consumed. 


14018       aONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

the  reduced  cost  being  passed  on  to  the  ultimate  consumer  of  the  canned  product 
and  "only  to  the  extent  that  the  consumption  of  canned  products  is  increased 
thereby.  Taking  into  account  the  low  elasticity  of  demand  for  canned  products, 
the  limited  degree  of  substitutability  attributable  to  price,  and  the  relative  un- 
importance of  the  price  of  the  tin  container  in  the  price  of  the  packaged  product, 
it  is  evident  that  the  demand  for  tin  plate  is  very  inelastic.  Fundamental  fac- 
tors such  as  consumers'  income  and  public  tastes  determine  the  demand  for 
canned  commodities  and,  hence,  the  consumption  of  steel  by  the  tin-can  indus- 
try. The  price  of  the  steel  consequently  is  of  minor  significance  in  determining 
this  consumption. 

III.  The  Container  Industry 

The  demand  for  steel  by  the  container  industry  is  a  derived  demand,  i.  e.,  it 
is  dependent  upon  the  factors  affecting  the  demand  for  containers.  Conse- 
quently, any  study  of  the  container  industry's  demand  for  steel  must  first  deal 
with  the  factors  which  have  a  bearing  on  the  demand  for  products  packed  in  tin 
containers. 

The  active  growth  of  the  canning  industry  in  this  country  began  in  the  period 
of  the  1860's  and  1870's;  by  the  turn  of  the  century  canneries  were  started  all 
over  the  country  for  fruits,  vegetables,  and  fish.^  Since  then  the  tin  container 
manufacturing  industry  has  progressed  rapidly.  Whereas  in  1904  this  industry 
had  a  value  of  product  0^41  million  dollars,  by  1937  the  product  totalled  350 
million  dollars.  In  the  latter  year  more  than  16  billion  cans  were  manufactured 
and  the  "tin  can  and  other  tinware"  industry  paid  out  37  million  dollars  in  wages 
and  245  million  dollars  for  materials,  fuel,  and  purchased  electric  energy. ^  It 
has  been  estimated  that  approximately  100  cans  per  year  are  made  in  the  United 
States  for  every  person  in  the  country.^ 

Tin  plate  is  suitable  for  containers  for  a  wide  variety  of  products  on  account 
of  its  cheapness,  strength,  lightness,  nontoxicity,  pleasing  and  sanitary  appear- 
ance, ease  of  fabrication,  durability,  bright  reflective  surface  and  suitability  for 
coating  and  decorating  by  lithographing.  The  use  of  the  tin  can  has  therefore 
expanded  in  the  food  packing  field  and  has  been  recently  extended  into  new 
fields,  such  as  motor  oil,  paints  and  varnishes,  pharmaceutical  and  toilet  articles, 
beer  and  tobacco. 

In  contrast  to  most  other  industries  consuming  steel,  the  tin  can  industry  has 
maintained  a  comparative  cyclical  stability,  with  small  fluctuations  even  in  the 
depression  period.  This  is  due  to  the  fact  that  canned  goods  are  mostly  perish- 
able consumers'  products,  i.  e.,  production  is  followed  more  or  less  immediately 
by  consumption  and  the  factor  of  durability  is  usually  not  involved  since  most 
cans  are  used  only  once. 

A  second  characteristic  of  the  tin  can  industry  is  the  relatively  steady  upward 
trend  in  can  production.  Basically,  this  trend  is  caused  by  new  and  more  di- 
versified uses  for  tin  cans.  These,  in  turn,  are  associated  with  public  tastes  and 
preferences  and  technological  advances  in  the  steel  and  container  industries. 

The  products  of  the  can  industry  can  be  grouped  under  two  heads: 

(a)  Food  or  Packer  cans,  which  include  most  of  the  tin  containers  for  food- 
stuffs, comprise  approximately  55  percent  of  the  total  value  of  all  products  of 
the  tin  can  industry.  More  than  11  billion  of  the  16  billion  cans  produced  in 
1937  were  of  this  type.^  In  1935  the  packer,  or  food,  cans  «  were  distributed 
among  products  as  follows:  57  percent  were  used  for  vegetables,  soups,  fruits 
and  juices;  25  percent  for  evaporated  milk;  15  percent  for  fish  and  meat;  and 
the  remaining  3  percent  were  used  for  food  specialties  and  dry  and  sweetened 
milk.^  Of  the  foods  canned,  there  are  many  varieties,  including  46  classes  of 
canned  vegetables,  33  classes  of  fruits,  10  classes  of  juices,  27  classes  of  fish  and 
shellfish,  41  classes  of  specialites,  23  classes  of  meats,  37  classes  of  soups  and  8 
classes  of  ready-made  entrees.* 

>  National  Canners  Association,  The  Canning  Industry,  March  1,  1939. 
'  Census  of  Manufactures,  1937,  "Tin  Cans  and  Other  Tinware",  release  October  12, 1938. 
^'International  Tin  Research  and  Development  Council,  Tin  Plate  and  Tin  Cans  in  the  Vnited  Stales 
(1936), p.  6. 
»  See  -Appendix,  Table  7. 

•  Although  there  are  27  different  sizes  of  sealed  cans  used  by  commercial  canners,  in  general  the  packers 
cans  are  standardized  in  size  and  shape. 

'  Evaporated  Milk  Association,  Some  Fads  About  Ecaporated  Milk  and  Other  Dairy  Products,  p.  19. 

•  American  Can  Company,  The  Canned  Food  Handbook,  pp.  14-16. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14019 


(b)  General  line  cans  totalled  nearly  5  billion  in  number  in  1937  and  represented 
45  percent  of  the  value  of  the  product  of  the  tin  can  industry."  These  general  line 
cans  are  of  innumerable  sizes  and  shapes  ranging  from  tiny  pill  boxes  to  large  oil 
cans  and  are  used  for  countless  varieties  of  commodities  which  do  not  require  heat 
treatment  in  the  packaging  process.'"  Among  the  most  important  products  packed 
in  general  line  cans  are  oil,  beer,  paints  and  varnishes,  bulk  milk  (which  is  placed 
in  large  dairy  milk  cans),  tobacco,  toilet  and  pharmaceutical  articles,  and  wax. 
It  should  be  noted  that  beer,  ice  cream,  dairy  milk,  and  coffee  cans  are  classed  in 
this  category  of  general  line  cans  in  spite  of  the  fact  that  the  products  contained 
in  such  cans  are  food  products. 

IV.  Steel  Consumption  by  the  Container  Industry 

The  consumption  of  st^el  as  a  raw  material  in  the  manufacture  of  tin  cans  and 
other  light  containers  has  shown  a  substantial  upward  trend  since  1923.  In  the 
period  from  1923-1929  this  industry  consumed  an  annual  average  of  1.42  million 
gross  tons  of  steel  but  in  the  period  from  1932-1938  its  consumption  averaged 
1.95  million  gross  tons,  an  increase  of  about  37  percent."  The  industry's  relative 
position  as  a  steel  consumer  has  also  risen;  in  1923  it  took  only  3.6  percent  of  the 
total  finished  rolled  steel  produced  in  this  country,  but  since  1932  it  has  taken 
nearly  9  percent  of  the  total  output.  In  1938  it  ranked  third  among  consuming 
industries,  accounting  for  9.1  percent  of  the  total  production  of  finished  steel.  The 
upward  trend  and  increasing  importance  of  the  container  industry  as  a  consumer 
of  steel  can  be  seen  from  the  following  table:  '^ 

Table  1. — Estimated  Consumption  of  Steel  by  the  Container  Industry,  192S-19S8 


Year 

Consumption 
of  Hot-Rolled 
Iron  and  Steel 
(thousands  of 
gross  tons) 

Percent  of 
Total  Hot- 
Rolled  Stee 
Production 

Year 

Consumption 
of  Hot-Rolled 
Iron  and  Steel 
(thousands  of 
gross  tons) 

Percent  of 
Total  Hot- 
Rolled  Steel 
Production 

1923 

1,205 
1,210 
1,427 
1,348 
1,408 
1,619 
1,707 
1,670 

3.6% 

4.3 

4.3 

3.8 

4.3 

4.3 

4.2 

5.7 

1931. 

1,415 
1,037 
1,759 
1,557 
2,039 
2,455 
2,874 
1,908 

7.4% 

1924.. 

1932.... 

1925 

1933 

1926 

1934 

8  2 

1927 

1935 

8.5 

1928 

1936 

7  3 

1929 

1937 

7  8 

1930 

Source:  Computed  by  apportioning  individual  hot-rolled  product  totals  on  the  basis  of  Iron  Age  dis- 
tribution reports  and  by  allocating  jobber  shipments  to  ultimate  consumers.  See  M.  W.  Worthing,  The 
Distribution  of  Steel  Products  to  Major  Consuming  Industries,  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  October  30, 


At  least  70  to  80  percent  of  the  steel  consumed  by  the  container  industry  is 
used  in  the  form  of  tin  plate  and  terne  plate  in  the  manufacture  of  packer  and 
general  line  cans.  In  the  production  of  tin  cans  the  most  important  raw  material 
is  tin  plate  which  consists  of  about  98  percent  steel  and  2  percent  tin.'^  The  cost 
of  tin  plate  represents  approximately  60  percent  of  the  value  of  the  tin  can." 
Terne  plate,  while  similar  to  tin  plate,  contains  some  lead  andjis  primarily  used, 
therefore,  for  non-food  products  such  as  lubricating  oil. 

Due  to  the  relative  stability  and  upward  trend  in  the  consumption  of  tin  plate, 
mills  engaged  in  its  production  were  operating  at  from  60  to  90  percent  of  capacity 
during  the  depression  while  the  steel  industry  as  a  whole  was  producing  at  from 

«  General  line  cans  and  packages  include  tin  boxes  and  pails.  In  general  the  total  value  of  product  of 
packers  and  general  line  cans  listed  here  was  335.0  million  dollars,  which  was  93.4  percent  of  the  total  value 
listed  for  the  tin  can  and  other  tinware  industry.  The  remainder,  i.  e.,  18.5  million  dollars,  represented 
finished  tinware  other  than  cans. 

10  Beer  is  an  exception,  requiring  heat  treatment. 

"  See  Table  1  in  text. 

»  The  series  of  "Tin  Plate  an4  Terne  Plate"  taken  from  the  Census  oj  Manufactures  shows  a  similar 
course.  See  Appendix,  Table  9.  Differences  in  the  two  tables  are  probably  due  to  varying  methods  of 
computation  and  different  coverage  and  classification. 

'3  National  Canners  Association,  Tlie  Story  of  the  Tin  Can,  and  American  Can  Company,  A  Word  about 
Tin  Cans,  p.  1. 

i<  See  Appendix,  Table  8. 


14020 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


15  to  60  percent  of  capacity. '^  The  upward  trend  in  the  consumption  of  tin  plate, 
most  of  which  is  used  in  the  production  of  tin  cans,"  can  be  seen  in  the  following 
table: 

Table  2. — Consumption  of  Tin  Plate  in  the  United  States,  1923-1935 


Total  Con- 
sumption 
(thousands 
of  gross  tons) 

Tin  Plate  Used  for  Packer 
Cans 

(Thousands 
of  gross  tons) 

(Percent  of 
total) 

1,291 
1,383 
1,348 
1,541 
1,293 
1,  579 
1,560 

661 
719 
702 

715 
738 
925 

51% 

52 

52 

58 

55 

47 

59 

Source:  International  Tin  Research  and  Development  Council,  Statistieal  Yearbook,  1939,  p.  134.  These 
figures  differ  from  the  estimates  given  in  Table  1  due  to  differences  in^overage  and  construction. 

V.  Relation  of  Price  to  Demand  for  Tin  Plate 

Total  consumption  of  steel  by  the  container  industry,  most  of  which  is  in  the 
form  of  tin  plate,  is  compared  with  an  index  of  the  price  of  tin  plate  from  1923  to 
1938  in  Chart  1."  This  chart  shows  the  marked  upward  trend  in  consumption 
of  steel  by  the  container  industry  during  this  period.  It  is  evident  from  the  chart 
that  the  relatively  large  fluctuations  in  steel  consumption  must  be  due  to  influences 
other  than  changes  in  the  price  of  tin  plate. 

In  order  to  determine  the  relative  importance  of  the  influence  of  the  price  of  tin 
plate  on  its  consumption  in  a  more  detailed  manner,  the  two  major  branches  of 
the  container  industry,  i.  e.,  packer  and  general  line  cans,  are  analyzed  to  discover 
the  extent  to  which  the  tin  plate  price  affects: 

(1)  the  output  and  consumption  of  all  canned  goods,  i.  e.,  all  goods  that  are 
put  in  containers; 

(2)  the  proportion  of  tliis  output  that  is  put  in  tin  cans;  and 

(3)  .the  amount  of  steel  in  the  tin  cans. 

A.  dem'and  for  food  or  packer  cans 

The  relative  stability  in  the  production  ot  food  cans,  which  constitute  55  percent 
of  the  total  value  of  all  tin  containers  and  consume  approximately  the  same  per- 
centage of  the  total  quantity  of  tin  plate  taken  by  the  container  industry,  is  due 
to  the  fact  that  food  in  general  is  a  necessity.  P'ood  expenditures  are  the  first  and 
greatest  expense  item  in  the  budget,  representing  approximately  35  percent  of  the 
expenditures  of  the  middle  income  class  's  and  higher  proportions  in  the  lower  in- 
come groups.''  While  consumers'  income  declined  28.5  percent  from  1929  to  the 
low  of  1932,  food  production  fell  only  10.3  percent.  In  the  recovery  through  1936, 
consumers'  income  rose  36.8  percent,  while  food  production  gained  only  3.4  per- 
cent.^"  Thus,  total  food  production  has  been  remarkably  stable,  showing  rela- 
tively less  fluctuation  than  has  consumers'  income  (Chart  2).  The  consumption 
of  canned  foods  ^i  has  fluctuated  in  the  cycle  in  close  relation  to  consumers'  income 
but  with  somewhat  greater  amplitude  than  total  food  production  (Chart  2). 


■5  International  Tin  Research  and  Development  Council,  Bulletin  4,  Tin  Plate  and  Tin  Cans  in  the 
UnUed  States.  1936,  p.  6.  .      ^     ^^  ■.  ^  c-.  . 

'6  International  Tin  Research  and  Development  Council,  Tin  Plate  and  Tin  Cans  m  the  United,  Stales 
(Bulletin  4,  Oct.,  1936),  p.  77.     In  addition,  .see  Iron  Age  (March  10,  1936),  p.  58A. 

i:  For  supporting  data,  see  Appendix,  Table  10.  .      „..,  ^    .    ^  r-  ■ 

IS  Works  Progress  Administration,  Division  of  Social  Research,  Inter-city  Differences  in  Cost  of  Living 
(March,  1935)  59  cities.  ^  .  ^       u  ,     4 

■  »  A  recent  survev  by  the  United  States  Department  of  Labor  found  that:  "Although  food  accounts  for 
approximately  two-fifths  of  the  total  expenditures  of  families  at  the  bottom  of  the  income  scale,  only  one-fifth 
or  less  of  the  expense  of  families  in  the  highest  income  level  is  accounted  for  by  food."  (United  States  De- 
partment of  Labor,  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics,  How  Urban  Families  Spend  Their  Incomes,  Release,  July  10, 
19.38.) 

"  See  Appendix,  Table  11.  ,    ..  ^  u  i 

21  This  close  relationship  between  canned  foods  and  consumers'  incomes  was  recently  borne  out  by  several 
studies  by  the  Division  of  Statistics  of  the  Natio.nal  Canners  Association.  These  studies  found  that  the 
chahges  in  emplovment  and  consumers'  buying  power  are  cf  great  importance  m  determmmg  both  the  prices 
and  consumption  of  the  h-ading  canned  vegetables:  cf.  National  Canners  Association,  padon  Affecting  Fro- 
duciion  and  Distribution  of  Canned  Peas,  Corn,  Tomatoes,  and  Snap  Beans,  and  also  CanniJ/  S^el  Corn  (igs^i. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14021 


"Vhe  relative  importance  of  consumers'  income  in  the  determination  of  the  con- 
sumption of  canned  foods  is  indicated  in  a  study  by  the  National  Resources  Com- 
mittee reported  in  "Patterns  of  Resource  Use."  22  There  it  is  shown  that  88 
percent  of  the  variation  in  the  consumption  of  canned  fruits  and  vegetables  is 
explained  by  two  factors,  consumer  income  and  a  time  trend.  Furthermore,  if 
the  residual  variation  in  consumption  not  accounted  for  by  these  factors  is  plotted 
against  an  index  of  canned  food  prices,  or  against  the  ratio  of  canned  food  prices 
to  general  food  prices,  no  relationship  is  evident.  Thus  the  price  of  canned  foods 
appears  not  to  have  been  an  important  factor  in  determining  their  consumption. ^^ 

Chart  1 


STEEL  CONSUMPTION  BY 
CONTAINER  INDUSTRY  AND  TIN  PLATE  PRICES 

inn                                                                                                                                                       '  '>~» 

9.0 

ao 
7ja 
6.0 
so 

AD 

ao 

1  - 

0 

"        1.0 

u.       09 

0       03 

0.7 

s   « 
i    " 

03 
02 

0.1 

1 

900 
800 
700 
600 
900 
400 

300 

200 

cc 

Ml 
00 

^"  i 

60  i 

50 

40 

30 
20 

10 

CO 

s 

STl 
><SU 

<T0 

\ 

.EL 
VI PT 

MS) 

ON 

"7 

/ 

/ 

\ 

- 

/ 

i!— 

^ 

^i 

=- 



— 

— ' 

W 

f^ 

h— 

h- 

— 

.... 

BTr 

P 

RICES 

I 

e  vd  Amenan  Imn  vrd  StK-l  Institute 

The  role  of  the  price  of  steel  entering  into  the  tin  can  in  which  food  is  packaged 
is  even  less  important.  It  can  only  affect  the  consumption  of  canned  products 
by  affecting  their  price.  But  the  cost  of  steel  used  in  tin  cans  constitutes  only 
a  small  part  of  the  retail  prices  of  the  canned  products'.  In  an  analysis  of  eleven 
leading  canned  vegetables  and  fruits,  it  was  found  that  in  only  four  cases  was  the 
cost  of  tin  plate  more  than  10  percent  of  the  final  retail  price  of  the  product;  in 
two  cases,  the  cost  of  tin  plate  was  less  than  5  percent  of  the  final  price;  while 
in  the  remaining  five  products,  the  cost  of  tin  plate  varied  from  5  to  10  percent 
of  the  retail  price.     The  following  table  lists  the  products,  their  retail  prices,  the 

32  Op.  cU.,  p.  103. 

"  The  investigations  by  Henry  Schultz,  Theory  and  Measurement  of  Demand,  Chipago,  1938,  show  that 
the  demand  for  most  agricultural  products  is  inelastic. 


14022 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  2 


CONSUMPTION  OF  CANNED  FOODS, 
FOOD  PRODUCTION  AND  CONSUMER  INCOME 

"900 
800 
700 
600 
500 
400 
300 

200 
CO 
ce. 

OD 

X         80 

s      ^° 

Z        60 
50 
40 

30 
20 

10 

1 

12 
70 
& 
50 
40 
30 

CO 

20       1 

-1 

§ 

■0      S 
8         to 

M 

5       -d- 

00 
4 

3 
2 

1 

___^ 

^ 

r=»^ 

^ 

-= 

s= 

= 

:J_ 

consumeF^ 

^ 

J 

^ 

A 

IlNCOMEp 

(1935DpLLARSP 

M 

c 
c 

/ 

IN 
ANN 
0. 

)EX 
ED 

OF 
FOO 
TIO 

3 

1^ 

- 

\ 

^ 

-^ 

/ 

A 

-<* 

r"- 

~*n^< 

— 

•■» 

•J 

^^Ts 

^ 

' 

'^Tdex  oN 

/ 

mnn 

f 

PRODUCTION 

P««;««  Ovrn/t^t.  ■■P^»^  cfResouxe  Us»"3nJ  U.S.B.LS. 

5 

itimated  tin  plate  cost,  and  the  estimated  proportion  that  such  tin  plate  cost 
orms  of  the  total  selling  price. 


Table  3.— Tin  Plate  Costs  in  Relation  to  Retail  Prices  of  Canned  Goods,  19S8 

Commodity 

Retail 
Price  > 
(cents) 

Estimated 

Tin  Plate 

Costs  • 

(cents) 

Tin  Pkte 
Cost  as  Pro- 
portion or 
Retail  Price 
(percent) 

8.8^ 
7.4 
U.2 
1L6 
16.1 
18.0 
21.3 
22.4 
13.4 
29.5 
26.7 

1.22e 
0.88 
1.22 
1.22 
1.22 
1.48 
1.48 
L48 
0.87 
L22 
0.87 

13.9% 

11.8 

10.9 

4.  Corn— No.  2  Standard 

10.6 

6.  Peas— No.  2  standard „ 

6.  Peaches— No.  2Hcan- .■... 

8.1 
8.0 

7.  Pears— No.  2]4  can                                .    . 

6.9 

8.  Pineapple— No.  2}^  can     .                               '               ^ 

6.6 

0.   PinV  KfilTTion — IfioJ!    Cfln,  Yftll 

6.6 

10.  Asparagus— No.  2  can 

11.  Canned  Sal    on— 16  oe.  o^,.tall ;.. 

4.1 
3.4 

Sources: 
>  United  States  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics,  Bulletin  635,  Indexes  of  Retail  PH«e  of  Food  In  51  CUies,  (1938). 
•  Calculated  by  assuming  a  60  percent  steel  proportion  (see  supra,  p.  6,  and  Appendix,  Table  8)  in  the 
price  of  tin  cans,  which  in  1938  were  as  follows: 

No.  1  TaU  can— 16  oz _ $14.56  per  1,000  cans 

No.  2W  Can— 1  lb.  1?  oz.. 24.71"      " 

No.  2  Can -1  lb.  3  oz ,.. 20.32"      " 

Almanac  of  the  Canning  Indxutry,  1939,  p.  236,  published  by  The  Canning  Trade. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14023 


Any  practical  reduction  in  the  price  of  tin  plate,  if  fuUy  reflected  in  the  price 
of  the  canned  food  products,  could  reduce  the  final  product  price  only  slightly. 
Even  a  10  percent  reduction  in  the  price  of  tin  plate,  if  passed  on  to  the  consumer, 
would  by  itself  lower  the  retail  prices  of  most  of  these  canned  food  products  by 
less  than  1  percent,  or  approximately  one-tenth  of  one  cent  per  can. 

Chart  3 


RELATION  OF  PACKS  OF  TOMATOES,  PEAS 
AND  CORN  TO  PRICE  OF  TIN  PLATE 

1921  - 1938 


TOM/ 

TOES 

1922 

1934 

I 

1925 

1927 

930*  1935 

•  1929 
•  1923 

1937 

192. 

1933  • 
1931 

1938* 
,•1528 

t-1936 
la24 
1926 

180 


PE 

\s 

1922 

• 

1935 

1937 

1933  • 

19i8 

•  1930 
1938» 

iWs* 

1923 

1934* 

1921 

• 

1332  « 

1926' 
^1931 

1925 
1927 

CO 

^N 

1925 

1935 

*937 

193! 
1933* 

1923 
1929 

.934 

• 

.19^ 
1930* 
1936 

^19?-? 
1926 

192! 

1932* 

.3?a 

VIZI 

80        F5        ^tO        95        100       i05       HO       115    -  !?0 
TIN  PLATE  PRICE  *n  PER  CENT  0"  PREVIOUS  VLAK 


20     w 
180    2 

140    ^ 

o 

100    h_ 

UJ 

O 

60     a: 

UJ 

a. 
20  ^ 
220    - 

t/> 

130    o 
o- 
140 

100 

60 

20 


Source:  Almonx  Of  Ccnnirg  InJusty  cr.o  Iron  Aqc 


The  relative  unimportance  of  the  price  of  tin  plate,  so  far  as  consumption  of 
of  canned  food  products  is  concerned,  is  confirmed  by  Chart  3  where  percentiige 
changes  in  the  production  of  canned  tomatoes,  peas  and  corn  arc  compared  with 
percentage  changes  in  the  price  of  tin  plate.-*  Since  changes  in  the  production 
of  these  products  have  not  been  associated  historically  with  changes  in  price 
of  tin  plate,  they  must  have  been  due  mainl\  to  the  inilueuce  cf  other  facturf . 

"  See  also  Apijeudli,  Table  12. 


14024       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

To  summarize:  The  cost  of  tin  plate  is  a  very  small  element  in  the  price  of 
canned  foods  and  therefore  changes  in  the  price  of  tin  plate  can  have  but  very 
slight  effect  on  the  price  and  consumption  of  canned  foods. 

There  is  still  the  question  of  the  possible  effect  of  the  price  of  tin  plate  on  the 
proportion  of  canned  food  output  that  is  put  in  cans  rather  than  in  containers 
made  'of  glass.^'  Among  the  factors  important  in  determining  this  proportion  are: 
(1)  the  relative  prices  of  the  different  types  of  containers;  (2)  public  taste,  custom 
and  convenience  (as  well  as  the  possibility  of  changing  these  by  advertising) ;  (3) 
technical  limitations  on  substitution;  and  (4)  the  existing  bottling  and  canning 
equipment  in  the  consumers'  goods  industries. 

Although  exact  information  on  prices  of  the  two  types  of  containers  is  not 
available,  a  rough  approximation  based  on  the  1935  Census  of  Manufactures  shows 
that  the  average  price  of  glass  containers  of  food  products  was  slightly  more  than 
2^  a  piece  and  the  average  price  per  food  can  was  slightly  less  than  2jf.28  These 
prices  are,  however,  not  strictly  comparable,  since  they  cover  all  types  and  sizes 
of  food  containers,  many  of  which  are  not  in  direct  competition,^?  and  since  they 
do  not  take  into  account  the  fact  that  the  tin  can  is  used  only  once  whereas  the 
glass  container  may  be  a  semi-durable  commodity  used  more  than  once.  How- 
ever, when  the  glass  food  container  is  not  returned,^^  the  total  original  cost  must 
enter  into  the  final  product  price  of  the  glass-contained  product  just  as  the  total 
initial  cost  of  the  tin  can  must  enter  into  the  selling  price  of  the  canned  goods. 
Although  in  general  the  price  of  tin  cans  for  food  is  slightly  lower  than  the  price 
of  glass  containers,  there  are  more  important  factors  determining  the  use  of  cans 
for  most  foods. 

First  of  all,  food  products  in  cans  have  come  to  be  accepted  and  even  pre- 
ferred because  of  certain  advantages  which  this  form  of  packaging  possesses. 
Cans  are  not  breakable;  they  are  readily  fabricated  in  desired  sizes,  weigh  less, 
require  less  space,  and  are  ea'  ier  and  cheaper  to  ship'  and  handle  than  bottles 
or  glass  containers.  Juices  wl  oh  "cloud  up"  do  not  lose  their  sale:;  value  in  cans. 
It  is  not  necessary  to  return  tl  ;  cans  and  no  deposit  or  bookkeeping  is  involved.^' 

Habit  and  custom  are  im^jortant  determinants  of  preferences  for  different 
types  of  containers.  Most  vegetables,  fruits,  evaporated  milk  and  fruit  juices 
have  found  acceptance  in  cans,  while  bottles  are  preferred  for  fresh  milk  and 
certain  beverages.  Of  late  there  has  been  a  growth  in  popularity  of  cans  over 
bottles  for  the  packaging  of  beverages  and  juices  for  consumption  in  the  home; 
experiments  are  being  carried  on  in  the  canning  of  ginger  ale,  coca-cola,  and  other 
liquids.  On  the  other  hand,  bottles  are  being  used  to  package  certain  high  priced 
vegetables  and  fruits.^"  Thus,  public  taste  and  custom,^'  which  are  of  major 
importance  in  determining  the  proportion  of  foods  packaged  in.  cans,  tend  to 
limit  the  substitution  of  cans  for  glass  containers  and  vice  versa  in  response  to 
price  changes. 

The  lines  of  competition  among  the  various  types  of  containers  have  also 
recently  been  extended  by  the  use  of  frozen  foods.  In  the  past  few  years  there  has 
been  a  marked  increase  in  the  packaging  of  frozen  fruits,  which  reached  a  total  of 
117.8  million  pounds  in  1938.^^  Part  of  the  frozen  food  pack  is  packaged  in  cans 
of  ordinary  food  sizes  (No.  10  can's)  and  in  larger  tin  containers  (10-50  pound 
and  1-5'  gallon  cans),  but  the  majority  of  the  frozen  foods  is  found  in  1  pound 
cartons  (cups  and  boxes).  In  general,  however,  these  frozen  foods  have  not  cut 
into  the  sale  of  vegetables  and  fruits  packed  in  tin  containers,  because  (1)  the 
frozen  foods  compete  mainly  with  fresh  foods,  (2)  they  are  higher  priced  than 
canned  foods,  (3)  many  homes  are  not  equipped  for  storage,  and  (4)  many  vege- 
tables and  fruits  have  not  yet  been  successfully  frozen. 

In  addition  to  the  public  taste,  the  chemical  and  physical  properties  of  foods 
give  rise  to  technical  limitations  on  the  kinds  of  food  put  in  tin  cans. 

Substitution  of  bottles  for  cans,  or  vice  versa,  is  restricted  by  the  costliness  of 
such  a  shift.     The  change  from  the  use  of  bottles  to  tin  cans  involves  the  cost  of 

2s  While  paper  container.s  are  useful  for  many  purposes,  they  seem  to  compete  more  directly  with^lass 
than  tin.  In  any  event,  competition  with  tin  plate  is  greatest  from  glass  and  the  discussion  is  confined 
primarily  to  that  problem.  Many  of  the  same  considerations,  however,  would  apply  to  competition  from 
other  types  of  containers,  including  paper. 

2«  Census  of  Manufactures,  1935,  pp.  842  and  958. 

'■  See  infra,  p.  15. 

"  Beverageand  milk  bottles  are  the  exceptions  here.  Their  original  costs  are  approximately  2.4d  and  3.6)! 
respectively.    Because  it  is  refilled  a  number  of  times,  the  average  cost  per  bottle  is  relatively  low. 

»  For  other  advantages  of  the  tin  can,  cf.  'Bnlletin  4,  of  International  Tin  Research  and  Development 
Council,  Tin  Plate  and  Tin  Cans  in  the  United  States  (1936),  pp.  8-9. 

M  Western  Canner  and  Packer,  Yearbook  and  Statistical  Number  (1939),  p.  174. 

"  Some  change  in  public  taste  may  be  effected  by  advertising  campaigns,  as  was  true  in  the  case  of  the 
beer  can.    See  infra,  pp.  15-16. 

32  Western  Canner  and  Packer,  op.  cit.,  p.  190. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14025 


scrapping  old  bottling  equipment  and  investing  in  new  canning  equipment. 
This  change  will  be  made  only  if  large  savings  are  realizable,  or  if  consumers' 
preferences  require  the   change. 

B.    DEMAND    FOR    GENERAL    LINE    CANS 

Many  consumers'  products,  such  as  oil,  paints  and  varnishes,  tobacco,  chemi- 
cals, pharmaceutical  and  toilet  articles,  spices,  beer,  and  coffee,  are  packaged  in 
general  line  cans.  As  previously  stated,  this  group  of  cans  accounts  for  approxi- 
mately 45  percent  of  the  total  quantity  of  tin  plate  taken  by  the  tin  can  industry. 

In  analyzing  the  demand  for  general  line  cans,  special  attention  will  be  devoted 
to  beer,  oil,  and  paint  and  varnish  cans.  These  are  the  most  important  of  the 
general  line  cans  and  illustrate  the  types  of  considerations  covering  the  demand 
for  such  containers. 

(1)  Beer  Cans.- — Of  the  general  line  cans,  beer  cans  are  today  among  the  most 
important.  In  1937  more  than  630  miUion  beer  cans  were  produced  with  a  value 
of  14  million  dollars  or  approximately  4  percent  of  the  total  value  of  all  the  tin 
cans  and  tin  utensils  produced  in  that  year.^^  Since  the  sale  of  beer  was  re- 
legalized  so  recently,  and  beer  cans  have  been  in  use  for  only  the  past  four  years, 
any  analysis  of  the  beer  industry's  consumption  of  tin  cans  necessarily  must  be 
tentative. 

As  shown  in  Table  4,  beer  consumption  has  had  an  upward  trend  since  re- 
legalizatioh  in  1933;  it  also  appears  to  respond  to  changes  in  consumers'  income. 

Table  4. — Production  of  Fermented  Malt  Liquors,  and  Consumers'  Income,  1934- 

1938 


Year 

Production  of  Fermented 
Malt  Liquors  ' 

Consumers'  Income ' 

Number  of 
barrels 

Index 
(1934=100) 

Millions  of 
dollars 

Index 
(1934=100) 

1934 

37, 678, 313 
45.  228,  605 
51,812,062 
58,  748. 087 
56,340,163 

100 

120 
138 
156 
150 

52, 057 
55,  814 

64,  207 
70,  694 

65,  021 

100 

1935 

107 

1936 " 

123 

1937 

136 

1938 

125 

Sources: 

1  United  States  Treasury  Department,  Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue  Alcohol  Tax  Unit,  Statistics  on  Fer- 
mented Mall  Liquors  and  Cereal  Beverages  (Fiscal  year  data). 

2  Survey  of  Current  Business,  June,  1939,  p.  12. 

With  the  increasing  consumption  of  beer,  there  has  been  a  shift  to  beer  pack- 
aged in  bottles  and  cans.  Packaged  beer  rose  from  20  percent  of  the  total  in 
1933  to  45  percent  in  1938.  Of  the  total  beer  packaged,  the  proportion  in  cans 
has  varied  only  from  13  percent  in  1935,  the  year  of  its  introduction,  to  17  percent 
in  1937.  Table  5  shows  the  percentage  of  all  beer  in  packaged  form  and  the 
percentage  of  packaged  beer  in  cans. 

Table  5.— Percentage  of  Beer  Packaged  in  Bottles  and  Cans,  1933-1938 


Year 

Percentage 
of  Beer 
Packaged 

Beer  in  Cans 
as  Percentage 
of  Total  Pack- 
aged Beer 

1933 - 

20% 

25 

30 

30 

44 

45 

(■) 

''    13% 

1934 

1935 _ 

1936 

1937 

1938  (4  mos.) 

Source;  Based  on  data  in  Metal  Containers,  August, 
1,  1938,  and  Steel,  January  6,  1936. 
'  Canned  beer  was  not  introduced  until  1935. 


8,  Canco,  October,  1935,  Sales  M^  nagement,  July 


Census  of  Manufacturers,  1937,  p.  2. 


14026       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  percentage  of  beer  put  in  cans  or  bottles  depends  upon  several  factors. 
First,  there  is  the  comparative  cost  of  container  and  transportation  for  bottled 
and  canned  beer.  Since  the  first  cost  of  a  beer  can  to  the  brewer  is  about  the  same 
as  the  cost  of  the  better  grade  of  bottle,"  re-use  of  the  bottle  '^  makes  it  a  cheaper 
packaging  medium.  On  tlie  other  hand,  transportation  costs  are  higher  for 
bottled  than  for  canned  beer.  Thus,  wide  geographical  distribution  of  a  parti- 
cular brand  of  beer  involving  considerable  transportation  costs,  danger  of  bottle 
breakage  and  recovery  difficulties  in  return  of  bottles  for  re-use  tend  to  make 
cans  less  costly  and  more  desirable  than  bottles.  Consequently,  in  the  export 
trade  ^^  and  where  the  beer  is  shipped  over  long  distances  in  the  domestic  market, 
the  tin  can  has 'made  Ifl-rge  inroads  in  the  bottled  beer  field. 

Secondly,  public  taste,  convenience  and  custom  are  important  considerations 
in  the  use  of  the  tin  can.  Tin  cans  save  space,  cool  more  quickly  than  bottles, 
and  do  not  require  a  deposit  or  bookkeeping.*'  On  the  other  hand,  bottled  beer 
was  estabhshed  before  Prohibition,  whereas  canned  beer  was  introduced  in  1935. 
In  restaurants,  taverns,  and  hotels  the  public  has  become  accustomed  to  bottled 
beer,  and  where  the  return  of  the  empty  bottle  is  not  a  problem,  these  intangible 
factors  have  a  marked  influence  pu  the  type  of  container  which  will  be  used.  Since 
the  introduction  of  tin  beer  cans,  the  can  companies  have  advertised  widely  *^ 
the  benefits  of  beer  in  cans,  and  pubUc  taste  and  custom  have  been  partly  altered 
in  favor  of  cans. 

The  cost  of  tin  plate  in  the  tin  beer  can  constitutes  on  the  average  less  than 
15  percent  of  the  retail  price  of  a  can  of  beer.*'  Consequently  a  10  percent  reduc- 
tion in  the  price  of  tin  plate,  if  passed  on  entirely  to  the  consumer,  would  reduce 
the  price  of  a  can  of  beer  by  only  about  fifteen  hundredths  of  one  cent.  Since 
the  cost  of  the  tin  plate  is  such  a  small  part  of  the  cost  of  a  can  of  beer,  and  the 
use  of  cans  for  beer  depends  largely  on  geographical  distribution  and  consumer 
acceptance,  a  change  in  the  price  of  tin  plate  can  have  only  a  slight  effect  on  the 
use  of  beer  cans. 

(2)  Lubricant  Oil  Cans. — The  lubricant  oil  industry  is  an  important  consumer 
of  tin  cans,  using  them  as  containers  for  its  products  in  both  domestic  and  export  *" 
markets.     Several  oil  companies  now  market  their  lubricants  exclusively  in  cans." 

The  demand  for  tin  cans  as  containers  for  motor  oil  depends,  of  course,  on  the 
demand  for  such  oil.  Lubricant  oil  consumption  has  shown  an  upward  trend 
since  1921,  which  has  been  mainly  due  (1)  to  the  increase  in  the  number  of  cars, 
total  motor  vehicle  registration  having  almost  tripled  from  1921  to  1937,  and 
(2)  to  the  70  percent  increase  in  the  average  mileage  per  car  in  this  same  period. 
The  following  table  shows  the  increase  in  the  lubricant  oil  consumption  and 
motor  vehicle  registrations  and  the  average  mileage  run  during  the  period  from 
1921  to  1937: 

Table  6. — Lubricant  Consumption,  Motor  Vehicle  Registration,  and  Average  Car 
Mileage,  1921-19S7 


Year 

Consumption 

of  Motor  Oil ' 

(thousands  of 

barrels) 

Total  Motor 
Vehicle  Regis- 
tration 2  (thou- 
sands of  ve- 
hicles) 

Mileage 
Run »  (aver- 
age per  car) 

1921    ....             .            . 

10.463 
19, 937 
26,501 
23,844 
29,705 

6,080 

9,221 
11,  526 

9,756 
12, 653 

6,896 

1929    .               ..                   

8,752 

1933    .                                       ..                                .             . 

8,864 

1937    . 

« 10, 304 

'  National  PelroUum  News,  January  11,  1939,  p.  24. 

'  Automobile  Facta  and  Fii/uren,  1938,  p.  16. 

«  O.  Terborgh,  Passenger  Automobiles  Memorandum,  April  12,  1937,  p.  2. 

♦  1936  figure  u.sed  here. 


"  See  Appendix,  Tables  14  and  15. 

"  In  1937  only  17%  of  the  beer  sold  as  packaged  beer  was  sold  in  can.-.,  the  balance  of  83%  being  sold  in 
bottles.  Since,  during  such  year,  only  673  million  beer  bottles  were  produced  as  contrasted  with  030  million 
beer  cans,  it  would  appear  that  each  beer  bottle  was  probably  used  on  an  average  of  Ave  times  (see  Table  5 
and  Appendix,  Ta()le  15). 

"  According  to  one  estimate,  eighty  percent  of  the  packaged  beer  in  the  e.xport  trade  is  in  cans.  (Steel, 
January  3.  1938,  p.  211.) 

"  International  Tin  Research  and  Development  Council,  Information  Circular  No.  1,  Canned  Beer 
(January,  1936). 

"  Sales  Management,  July  1,  1938. 

"  See  Appendix,  Tables  8  and  14. 

«»  R.  Skoinp,  The  Evolution  of  a  7'in  Can,  p.  16. 

*'  International  Tin  Research  and  Development  Council,  Tin  Plate  and  Tin  Cans  in  the  United  States, 
Bulletin  No.  4  (1930).  p.  115. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14027 

This  great  increase  in  the  consumption  of  lubricant  oil  has  brought  an  increase 
in  the  use  of  oil  cans."  As  in  the  beer  industry,  the  consumers  in  the  past  few 
years  have  learned  the  advantages  of  oil  in  sealed  cans  and  have  accordingly 
increased  their  consumption  of  oil  in  such  containers.^'  Customers  prefer  such 
tin  cans  due  to  the  assurance  that  the  oil  is  free  from  contamination  or  substitu- 
tion, and  retailers  favor  canned  oil  because  it  is  convenient  and  suitable  for 
attractive  displays  and  it  permits  greater  diversification  in  grade  of  oil."  In 
part,  however,  the  tendency  to  favor  oil  in  cans  is  offset  by  declines  in  consumers' 
income,  for  a  drop  in  income  leads  to  the  purchase  of  the  cheaper  grades  of  oil, 
which  are  sold  in  bulk.'*5 

(3)  Paint  and  Varnish  Cans. — Consumption  of  general  line  cans  by  the  paint 
and  varnish  industry  has  shown^  an  upwarS  trend  subject,  however,  to  wide 

•  fluctuations.  Production  of  paints  and  varnishes  rose  steadily  from  1919  to  a 
peak  in  1929,  declined  45  percent  to  a  low  in  1932,  and  by  1935  recovered  to 
87  percent  of  the  1929  level.'"  The  report  of  the  National  Resources  Committee 
in  Patterns  of  Resource  Use  found  that  the  consumption  of  paints  and  varnishes 
was  closely  related  to  consumers'  income.*^ 

Since  the  cost  of  tin  plate  is  only  a  fraction  of  the  cost  of  the  finished  product 
in  a  thi  container  and  since  substitution  of  tin  cans  for  other  types  of  containers 
is  a  minor  factor,  tin  plate  prices  are  relatively  unimportant  in  their  effect  on 
the  consumption  of  paints  and  varnishes. 

(4)  Other  General  Line  Cans. — Other  industries  which  use  general  line  con- 
tainers also  reflect  this  same  general  pattern  of  upward  trend  and  dependence 
on  consumers'  income.  Automobile  pohshes,  waxes,  and  anti-freeze  solutions 
sold  in  cans  reflect  the  growth  in  the  number  and  use  of  automobiles.  The 
tobacco  and  chemical  industries,*^  which  use  tin  containers,  both  show  a  high 
degree  of  correlation  with  consumers'  income. 

The  demand  for  general  line  cans  necessarily  follows  closely  the  production  .of 
the  products  packed  in  the  cans,  which,  in  turn,  is  generally  dependent  prima,rily 
upon  consumers'  income.  The  cost  of  tin  plate,  which  constitutes  a  small  portion, 
usually  less  than  10  percent,  of  the  retail  price,  is  therefore  only  a  minor  influence 
in  determining  consumption  of  tin  plate  by  these  industries.  Possibilities  of 
substituting  general  line  tin  cans  for  other  typgs  of  containers  by  a  price  reduction 
tend  to  be  limited  due  to  other  factors  such  as  fixity  of  public  taste  and  diflSculties 
of  technical  adaptation. 

C.    QUANTITY    OF   TIN    PLATE    PER    CAN 

The  quantity  of  tin  plate  used  in  any  specified  tin  can  depends  almost  entirely 
on  the  product  to  be  packed.  The  specifications  for  the  composition  of  the  tin 
plate,  the  manner  of  processing  and  the  weight  and  amount  of  tin  plate  in  the 
tin  cans  depend  upon  (1)  variable  corrosion,  deformation  and  the  other  technical 
matters  encountered  in  the  packing  of  the  different  food  stuffs  and  other  materials 
and  (2)  needs  of  the  canners,  retailers,  and  consumers.*'  These  technical  factors 
control  the  quantity  of  tin  plate  used  in  a  can  designed  for  a  particular  use. 

VI.  Summary 

The  price  of  tin  plate  is  of  minor  significance  in  determining  its  consumption. 
Since  the  demand  for  products  packed  in  tin  cans  is  generally  not  very  elastic, 
and  especially  since  the  cost  of  tin  plate  is  such  a  small  proportion  of  the  cost  of 
the  final  product,  a  reductio  i  in  the  price  of  tin  plate>  would  be  ineffectual  in  in- 
creasing the  consumption  of  steel.  More  fundamental  forces  such  as  consumers' 
income,  public  tastes,  and  technical  considerations  determine  the  demand  for 
canned  commodities  and,  hence,  the  consumption  of  tin  plate  by  the  canning 
industry. 

"  Steel,  January  2, 1939,  p.  149,  and  International  Tin  Research  and  Development  Council,  op.  cit.,  p.  115. 

"  Sales  Management,  July  1,  1938,  p.  50. 

"  International  Tin  Research  and  Development  Council,  op.  cit.,  pp.  115-6. 

"Si«e;,  April  11,  1938,  p.  23. 

*o  National  Resources  CMnmittee,  Patterns  of  Resource  Use,  PreUminary  Edition  for  Technical  Criticism, 
March,  1939.  p.  122.    See  also  Appendix,  Table  16. 

"  The  amount  of  variation  in  the  consumption  of  paints  and  varnishes  explained  by  consumers'  income 
!S95  percent.    Ibid. 

*8  ThejNational  Resources  Committee  found  that  tobbacco  consumption  was  related  to  consumer  income 
and  a. time -trend  and  that  the  amount  of  variation  explained  was  96  percent;  also  that  the  consumption 
of  chemicals  was  related  to  consumers'  income  and  the  Federal  Reserve  Board's  index  of  industrial  pro- 
duction, and  that  the  amount  of  variation  explained  was  93  percent.  Cf.  National  Resour^is  Committee, 
op.  cit.,  pp.  104  and  121.  '  Also  see  Appendix,  Tables  17  and  18. 

"  International  Tin  Research  and  Development  Council,  op.  cit.,  especially  pp.  67  and  88,  and  also  th' 

'--'    '  General  Report, -1 937,  by  the  Council. 

124491— 41— pt.  26 29 


14028  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Appendix 
Table  7.— Production  of  Tin  Cans  and  Utensils,  19S7 


Type  of  Can 

Number 
(millions 
of  cans) 

Value 
(millions 
of  dollars) 

Percent  of 
Total 
Value 

Packers  Cans: 

1,800.1 
9, 592.  2 

'  4, 190. 1 

630.9 
1.0 
1.6 

$16.1 
188.9 

130.4 

14.1 
0.5 
5.0 

4.8% 

Sanitary  cans  (including  sweetened  condeased  milk  cans) 

General  Line  Cans: 

50.4 

Special  general  line  cans: 

4.2 

0.2 

1.6 

Total  tin  cans,  utensils,  etc 

1  16,215.9 

»  335. 0 

100.0 

1  The  number  of  cans  listed  here  is  only  the  number  reported  whereas  the  value  is  for  all  cans,  including 
8  million  dollars  worth  of  cans  for  which  numbers  were  not  reported. 

•  Includes  tin  cans,  utensils,  etc.,  made  as  secondary  products  in  other  industries  but  does  not  include 
$18,537,673  of  finished  tinware,  other  than  cans. 

Sources:  Censiis  of  Manufactures,  1937,  "Tin  Cans  and  Other  Tinware." 
Table  8 
SECTION  A— STEEL  COSTS  IN  THE  TIN  CAN  INDUSTRY,  1935 

Value  of  Products  of  the  Tin  Can  and  Other  Tinware  Industry  K.  $287,  582,  216 

Cost  of  Steel  Materials  Used  in  the  Tin  Can  Industry  2 170,  665,  145 

Steel  Costs  as  Proportion  of  Total  Value  of  Products  of  the  Tin 

Can  Industry  3 59.  3% 

Sources:  '  Census  of  Manufactures,  1935,  "Tin  Cans  and  Other  Tinware,"  p.  958.  The  coverage  here 
is  the  same  as  for  the  steel  materials  and  represents  98.4  percent  of  the  aggregate  value  of  products  for  the 
industry. 

2  See  Section  B  below. 

3  Computed  by  dividing  cost  of  steel  materials  by  value  of  product. 

SECTION  B— STEEL  MATERIALS  CONSUMED  BY  THE  TIN  CAN  INDUSTRY,  1935 


Quantity 
Reported 
(net  tons)' 


Tin  plate--. 
Teme  plate - 
Black  plate. 


$159,938,020 
5,911,536 
4,815,589 


,404,948 
61, 193 
63,745 


All  products- 


Source:  Census  of  Manufactures,  1935,  "Tin  Cans  and  Other  Tinware,"  p.  958. 

1  The  reported  tons  cover  95  percent  of  the  cost  figures  given,  for  in  some  cases  only  the  value  was  reported . 

Table  9. —  Tin  plate  and  terne  plate  production,  1919-1937 


Year 

Total  Produc- 
tion of  Tin 
Plate  and 
Terne  Plate 

(thousands  of 
pounds) 

Total  Value  of 

Tin  Plate  and 

Terne  Plate 

(thousands  of 

dollars) 

Year 

Total  Produc- 
tion of  Tin 
Plate  and 
Terne  Plate 
(thousands  of 
pounds) 

Total  Value  of 
Tin  Plate  and 

erne  Plate 
(thousands  of 

dollars) 

1919 

2,  539,  224 
1,  725, 781 

3,  296, 551 
3,661,837 
3,  753,  474 

$175, 776 
96,181 
162,  476 
188, 610 
190, 426 

1929 

4,  377,  488 
3, 268, 025 

3,  962,  956 

4,  216,  002 
6,  022,  908 

209.675 

1921 

1931 

140,  984 

148,  770 

1925        .... 

192,  323 

1927 

1937 

278,  380 

Source:  Census  of  Manufactures,  "Tin  Plate  and  Terne  Plate." 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        14029 

Table  10. — Prices  of  tin  plate  and  consumption  of  steel  by  the  container  industry, 
1923-1938 


Tin  Plate  Prices ' 

Consumption 
oT  Hot-Rolled 
Iron  and  Steel 
(thousands  of 
gross  tons)  2 

Year 

Tin  Plate  Prices  i 

Consumption 
of  Hot-Rolled 

Year 

(Dollars  per 
base  box) 

Inde.x 
(1929=100) 

(Dollars  per 
base  box) 

Index  • 
(1929=100) 

Iron  and  Steel 
(thousands  of 
gross  tons)' 

1923 

1924 

1925 

1926... 

1927 

1928 

1929 

1930 _ 

$5,42 
5.50 
5.50 
5.50 
5.48 
5.25 
5.35 
5.19 

101 
103 
103 
103 
102 

98 
100 

97 

1,205 
1,210 
1,427 
1,348 
1,408 
1,619 
1,707 
1,670 

1931 

1932 

1933- -- 

1934 

1935-. 

1936 

1937 

1938 

4.94 
4.69 
4.43 
5.25 
5.25 
5.25 
35.22 
35.31 

92 

88 

98 

98 

»105 

'103 

1,415 
1,037 
1,769 
1,557 
2,039 
2,455 
2,784 
1,908 

Source: 

1  Iron  Age,  January  5,  1939,  p.  198.    These  figures  are  average  prices  for  the  year  at  Pittsburgh. 

'  Computed  by  apportioning  individual  hot-rolled  product  totals  on  the  basis  of  Iron  Age  distribution 
reports  and  by  allocating  jobber  shipments  to  ultimate  consumers.  See  M.  W.  Worthing.  The  Distribution 
of  Steel  Products  to  Major  Consuming  Industries,  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  October  30,  1939. 

3  For  a  number  of  years  prior  to  1937,  published  prices  were  subject  to  a  trade  discount  of  7^i  percent. 
Since  January  1,  1937,  the  published  prices  have  been  net.  From  January  1,  1938,  to  November  10,  1938, 
there  was  a  refund  of  250  per  base  box.  A  nominal  list  price  comparable  to  those  in  the  years  preceding 
1937,  which  takes  these  two  factors  into  account,  would  have  been  $5.64  in  1937  and  $5.51  in  1938.  The 
index  figures  shown  in  the  table  for  1937  and  1938  are  based  upon  these  nominal  list  prices. 

<  Strip  was  included  in  container  industry  tonnage  in  1938. 


Table   U. 


-Consumers'  income,  food  production,  and  canned  food  consumption, 
1919-1936 


Consumers' 

Income 

(biUions  of 

1936  doiiars) ' 

Index  of 
Food  Pro- 
duction 
(1923- 
1925  =  100 » 

Consumption  of  Canned 
Foods 

Year 

Amount 
(millions  of 
pounds)  3 

Index 

(1923- 

1925=100) 

1919 

$46.6 
47.0 
42.3 
48.8 
54.8 
55.4 
57.0 
58.3 
58.9 
62.2 
65.3 
60.4 
54.6 
46.7 
48.2 
54.0 
56.9 
63.9 

94 
84 
83 
94 
99 
103 
98 
97 
96 
98 
97 
93 
90 
87 
92 
99 
79 
90 

(*) 

(*) 
1891 
2620 
2890 
2931 
3847 
3493 
3590 
3822 
4096 
4218 
3404 
3282 
3568 
3973 
4753 

(') 

(<; 
59 

1920 

1921 

1922 

81 

1923 

90 

1924 

1925 

1926 

1927 

1928 

1929 

127 

1930 

131 

1931 

106 

1932 

102 

1933 

1934 

123 

1935 

1936    .             

0) 

Sources: 

'  National  Resources  Committee,  Patterns  of  Resource  Use,  March,  1939,  p. 
'  Federal  Reserve  Board,  Division  of  Research  and  Statistics,  June,  1937. 
5  National  Resources  Committee.  Patterns  of  Resource  Use.  March.  1939.  p. 
*  Data  not  given. 


14030       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  12.— Food  Packs  and  Tin  Plate  Price,  1920-19S8 


Food  Packs  <  (thousands  of  cases) 

Price  of  Tin 
Plate  >  (dol- 
lars per  base 
box) 

#3  Tomatoes 

#2  Corn 

#2  Peas 

1920                               - 

U,  368 

4,017 
11,538 
14,672 
12, 519 
19, 770 

9,455 
13, 137 

8,639 
14, 146 
16,998 

9,573 
16,028 
11,986 
22, 376 
26,985 
24,209 
26, 076 
22,960 

15,040 
8,843 
11,419 
14, 106 
12,131 
24.320 
19,069 
10,347 
14, 497 
17, 487 
15,692 
19,415 
9,358 
10,193 

2l',471 
14,621 
23,541 
20,470 

12, 317 
8,207 
13,042 
13,948 
19.315 
17,816 
17, 709 

it!  943 
18,530 
22,035 
13,286 
10, 367 
12, 893 

15,  742 
24,699 

16,  553 
23.467 
25,459 

$7.53 

1921 

6.90 

4.73 

5.42 

5.50 

5.50 

5.50 

6.48 

5.25 

5.35 

J930                                                      .     . 

6.19 

(931                                                      ..  , 

4.94 

(932                                                  

4.69 

1933                                                 

.    4.43 

1934                                            

5.25 

1935 

1936                                   - 

5.25 
5.25 

1937                                   .     ..  

'5,22 

1938 

«5.31 

I  Data  on  packs  from  The  Canning  Trade,  Almanac  of  the  Cannino  Industry,  1939,  p.  208. 

»  Irmi  Age,  January  5, 1939,  p.  200.    These  figures  are  averages  for  the  year  and  represent  tin  plate  prices 

« A  list  price  comparable  to  those  in  the  years  preceding  1937  would  have  been  $5.64  in  1937  and  $6.51 
in  1938.    See  note  3  to  Table  10. 


Table  13. 


-Prices  of  Tin  Plate  and  Average  Retail  Prices  of  Canned  Foods  in  51 
Cities  Combined,  1 923-1938 


Canned  Foods  '  (cents  per  can) 

Tin  Plate  > 
(dollars 

Yeu 

Salmon 

Red(16oz. 

can) 

Peas 
(No.  2  can) 

Cora 
(No.  2  can) 

Tomatoes 
(No.  2  can) 

Milk 

Evaporated 

(14!^  oz. 

can) 

1923 

30.  US 
30.1 
32.2 
36.6 
32.7 
33.7 
-  31.1 
32.1 
32.2 
24.3 
19.3 
21.1 
22.1 
25.3 
25.6 
25.7 

17.3(f 
17.9 
17.9 
17.1 
16.5 
16.0 
16.5 
16.0 
14.0 
12.7 
12.8 
16.6 
17.1 
16.1 
16.2 
15.1 

15.4»f 
16.0 
17.6 
16.3 
15.7 
15.9 
15.8 
15.3 
13.3 
10.6 
10.1 
11.5 
12.5 
12.0 
12.9 
11.6 

12. 5< 
12.8 
13.2 
11.8 
11.9 
11.7 
12.8 
12.1 
10.1 
9.3 
9.1 
10.5 
10.1 
9.4 
9.3 
8.8 

10.9(» 
10.2 
10.2 
10.3 
10.-3 
10.0 
9.8 
9.1 
8.2 
6.8 
6.5 
6.7 
7.0 
7.6 
7.6 
7.1 

$5.4» 

1924 

5.50 

1925                                

5.50 

1926                                

5.60 

1927                                 

6.48 

1928— - 

6.25 

1929                      .  .  

6.35 

1930 

5.19 

1931                   

4.94 

4.69 

1933 

4.43 

5.25 

5.25 

5.25 

•5.22 

»5.31 

Sources: 

1  Retail  Prices  of  F^od,  1923-36,  United  States  Dept.  of  Labor,  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics,  pp.  80-90.  Also 
Retail  Prices,  Jan..  19,33,  p.  12.  and  Jan.  1939,  pp.  12, 13. 

"  Tin  plate  prices  are  average  prices  for  the  year  at  Pittsburgh.    Cf.  Iron  Age,  January  5. 1939,  p.  200. 

>  A  list  price  comparable  to  those  in  the  years  preceding  1937  would  have  been  $5.04  in  1937  and  $5.51  in 
1938.    See  note  3  to  Table  10. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14031 

Table  14. — Cost  of  Containers  and  Retail  Price  of  Beer,  New  York  City 


Type  of  Container 

Cost  of  Con- 
tainer (cents 
per  can)' 

Retail  Price  of  Beer 
(cents  per  can) 

Locally  pro- 
duced 

Produced 
elsewhere 

Cans 

2. 136fi 
>2.100 

10.0)! 

10. 0  to  12. 5^ 
»12.S 

Bottles 

Source:Informationsuppliedbytrade,  October,  1939. 


Prices  quoted  in  quantities  of  1,000  units. 

Represents  better  class  of  bottles,  re-used  a  number  of  times.    For  a  cheaper  grade  of  re-used  bottles  the 


price  quoted  was  $19.90  per  1000  and  for  "one-trip"  bottles  it  was  $17.55  per 
can  and  bottle  in  Table  15. 
'  Prices  quoted  for  case  of  24  cans  or  bottles.    Bottle  deposits  excluded. 


Compare  average  value  of 


Table  15. — Beer  Bottles  and  Beer  Cans,  1937 


Number 
Produced 

Value  of 
Product 

Average 
Value  per 
Container 

Beer  bottles 

673,053,408 
630,896,567 

$13, 382, 049 
14,108,829 

i.m 

%2\t 

Beer  cans. 

Source:  Census  of  Manufactures,  1937,  "Glass"  and  "Tin  Cans  and  Other  Tinware". 
Table  16. — Production  of  Paints  and  Varnishes,  and  Consumers'  Income,  19 19-1985 


1920 
1921 
1922 
1923 
1924 
1925 
1926 
1927 


Index  of 

Varnish 

and  Paint 

Production 

(1929=100) 


49.9 
54.  G 
44.6 


67.5 
71.0 
78.7 
79.6 
87.6 


Consumers' 

Income 
(billions  of 
1935  dollars) 


46.6 
47.0 
42.3 
48.8 
54.8 
55.4 
57.0 
58.3 
58.9 


1930. 
1931. 
1932. 
1933. 
1934. 
1935. 


Index  of 
Varnish 
and  Paint 
Production 
(1929=100) 


96.2 
100.0 
81.6 
70.6 
5.5.6 

70!7 


Consumers' 

Income 
(billions  of 
1936  dollars) 


62.2 
65.3 
60.4 
54.6 
46.7 
48.2 
M.O 
66.9 


Source:  National  Resources  Committee,  Patterns  of  Resource  Use,  Preliminary  Edition  for  Technical 
Criticism,  1939,  p.  122. 

Table   17. —  Tobacco  Consumption  and  Consumers'  Income,  1919-1936 


Year 

Tobacco 
Consump- 
tion (1923- 
1925=100) 

Consumers' 

Income 
(billions  of 
1936  dollars) 

Year 

Tobacco 
Consump- 
tion (1923- 
1925  =  100) 

Consumers' 

Income 
(billions  of 
1936  dollars) 

1919 

82 

87 
85 

96 

105 
112 

lis 

$46.6 
47.0 
42.3 
48.8 
54.8 
.55.4 
57.0 
58.3 
58.9 

124 
134 
131 
123 
111 
116 
128 
135 
151 

62.2 
65.3 
60.4 
54.6 
46  7 

1920 

1921 

1930 

1922 

1931 

1923 

1932 

1924 

48  2 

1925 

54.0 
56.9 

1926.. 

1927 

Source:  National  Resources  Committee   Patterns  of  Resource  Use,  Preliminary  Edition  for  Technical 
Criticism,  1938,  p.  104. 


14032  CONCP]NTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table   18. — Consumption  of  Chemicals,   Industrial  Production,   and   Consumers' 
Income,  1 923-1935 


Year 

Consump- 
tion of 

Chemicals 
(1929  = 
100)1 

Average 
Industrial 
Production 
and  Con- 
sumers' 
Income 
(1923-5 
=  100) » 

Consumers' 
Income 

(billions  of 

1936 

dollars) 

Year 

Consump- 
tion of 

Chemicals 
(1929  = 
100)' 

Average 
Industrial 
Production 
and  Con- 
sumers' 
Income 
(1923-5 
=  100)  ' 

Consumers' 
Income 

(biUions  of 

1936 

dollars) 

1923 

1924 - 

1925 

1926.. 

1927 

1928 

1929 

64.1 
58.1 
66.6 
76.4 
75.2 
92.2 
100.0 

100 
97 
103 
106 
106 
112 
118 

54.8 
55.4 
57.0 
58.3 
68.9 
62.2 
65.3 

1930... 

1931 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 -. 

89.7 
78.2 
61.3 
77.8 
87.5 
90.7 

102 
90 
74 
81 
88 
96 

60.4 
54.6 
46.7 
48.2 
54.0 
56.9 

Sources:  National  Resources  Committee,  Patterns  of  Resource  Use,  Preliminary  Edition  for  Technical 
Criticism,  1939,  p.  121. 

'  The  production  series  given  in  summary  was  adjusted  for  imports  and  exports  as  given  in  the  Statistical 
Abstract  of  the  United  StaUs. 

2  Consmer  income  is  reduced  to  a  1923-25  base;  this  is  combined  with  the  Federal  Reserve  Board  index 
of  industrial  production,  each  series  being  weighted  equally. 


Exhibit  No.  1416 

AN    ANALYSIS    OF    STEEL    PRICES,    VOLUME    AND    COSTS- 
CONTROLLING  LIMITATIONS  ON   PRICE   REDUCTIONS 


Thia  analysis  was  prepared  by  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  in  connec- 
tion with  its  studies  in  preparation  for  the  hearings  on  the  steel  industry  before 
the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee.  The  work  was  under  the  super- 
vision of  Theodore  O.  Yntema,  Professor  of  Statistics,  University  of  Chicago. 

October  30,  1939. 

TABLE  OF  COIfTENTS 
I.  Purpose  of  the  Study. 
II.  Summary  of  Findings. 

III.  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  Costs  in  Relation  to  Volume. 

IV.  Composition  of  Costs. 

V.  Relation  of  Costs  and  Volume  to  Prices. 
VI.  Weighted  Tonnages  and  the  Operating  Rate. 
Appendix  I— Computation  of  Average  Worliing  Capital— 1938. 
Appendix  II— Computation  of  Percentage  Increase  in  Volume  to  be  Expected  from  Percentage  Decrease  in 

Price,  assuming  Elasticity  of  Demand  for  Steel  of  1. 
Appendix  III— Actual  Operating  Deficit  in  1938  and  Estimated  Addition  to  Deficit  if  Prices  Had  Been 

Further  Reduced. 
Appendix  IV — Weighted  Tonnage  which  Must  Be  Shipped  to  Break  Even  at  Various  Price  I/Cvels. 
Appendix  V— Computation  of  Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Offset  Decreases  in  Price. 
Appendix  VII— Operating  Rate  Required  to  Earn  5%  on  Tangible  Investment  if  Break-even  Point  were 

at  over  90%  of  Capacity. 
Appendix  VII— Effect  of  Inter-company  Transactions  on  Profit  and  Loss  Statement. 

Tables 

Table  1— Elements  of  Total  Costs— 1938  Conditions^ 

Table  2— Estimated  Additions  to  1938  Deficit— How  Deficit  Would  Have  Increased  if  Prices  Had  Been 
Reduced  and  Volume  Had  Increased  to  Same  Relative  Extent. 

Table  3— Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Decreases  in  Average  1938  Prices,  Compared  to 
Maximum  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume. 

Table  4— Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Decreases  in  Average  1938  Pri(tes,  Compared  to 
Maximum  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume. 

Table  5— Compilation  of  Total  Costs  Exclusive  of  Inter-company  Items  and  Casts  Connected  with  Extra 
neous  Transactions. 

Table  6— Estimate  of  Inter-company  Transactions. 

Table  7— Total  Costs  and  Volume  of  Busine.ss- Unadjusted. 

Table  8— Analysis  of  Operating  Costs  into  Components. 

Table  9 — Taxes  and  Volume  of  Business. 

Table  10— Estimated  Ta\es  (Other  than  Social  Security  and  Federal  Income)  in  Prior  Years  if  1932-1938 
Rates  Had  Prevailed. 

Table  11— Taxes  and  Volume  of  Business,  under  Present  Tax  Laws. 

Table  12— Adjustment  of  Payroll  to  1938  Wage  Rates. 

Table  13— Estimate  of  Social  Security  Taxes  at  1938  Rates. 

Table  14— "Other  Expenses"  Adjusted  for  Changes  in  Price  Level. 

Table  15-  Costs  Adjusted  to  1938  Interest,  Tax,  Pension,  and  Wage  Rates  and  1938  Price  Levels,  but  Unad- 
justed for  Secular  Trend. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       14033 

Table  16 — Deviation  of  Adjusted  Total  Costs  from  Average  Costs  for  Volume  Involved. 

Table  17— Adjustment  of  Adjusted  Costs  for  Time  Trend. 

Table  18— Total  Costs  of  Operations  and  Volume  of  Business— 1938. 

Table  19 — Deviation  of  Payrolls,  Adjusted  to  1938  Wage  Rates,  from  Average  Payroll  for  Volume  Involved. 

Table  20— Adjustment  of  Payrolls,  Adjusted  to  1938  Wage  Rates,  for  Time  Trend. 

Table  21— Payrolls,  Adjusted  to  1938  Wage  Rates  and  EflSciency,  and  Volume  of  Business— 1938. 

Table  22 — Deviation  of  Adjusted  "Other  Expenses"  from  Average  for  Volume  Involved. 

Table  23 — Adjustment  of  Adjusted  "Other  Expenses"  for  Time  Trend. 

Table  24 — "Other  Expenses,"  Adjusted  to  1938  Price  Levels  and  Operating  Conditions,  Related  to  Volume 

of  Business— 1938. 
Table  25— Elements  of  Total  Costs  Adjusted  to  1938  Conditions. 
Table  26— Elements  of  Total  Costs— Revised— 1938  Conditions. 
Table  27— Cash  and  Non-Cash  Costs— 1938  Conditions. 

Table  28— Percentage  of  Fixed  to  Total  Costs  at  Various  Rates  of  Operation— 1938  Conditions. 
Table  29— Sales  and  Other  Operating  Revenues— 1938. 

Table  30 — Transportation  and  Miscellaneous  Revenues  Related  to  Volume  of  Business. 
Table  31— Transportation  and  Miscellaneous  Revenues  per  Weighted  Ton  of  Products  Shipped. 
Table  32— Estimated  Additions  to  1938  Deficit— How  Deficit  Would  Have  Increased  if  Prices  Had  Been 

Reduced  Various  Percentages. 
Table  33— Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Various  Reductions  in  Average  1938  Prices, 

Compared  to  Maximum  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume. 
Table  34 — Estimate  of  Annual  Sales  and  Revenue  at  Prices  Prevailing  in  Second  Half  of  1938. 
Table  35 — Increase  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Various  Reductions  in  the  Prices  Prevailing  in 

the  Second  Half  of  1938,  Compared  to  Maximum  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume. 
Table  36— Weighted  Tonnages  of  All  Tonnage  Products  and  Unewighted  Tonnages  of  Rolled  and  Finished 

Products  Shipped. 
Table  37— Average  Weighted  Equivalent  of  Unweighted  Tonnages. 

Table  38— Ratio  of  Tons  of  Rolled  and  Finished  Products  to  Weighted  Tons  of  All  Tonnage  Products. 
Table  39— Percentage  of  Tons  of  Various  Classes  of  Products  Shipped  to  Total  Tons  of  Rolled  and  Finished 

Products  Shipped— 1927-1938. 
Table  40— Ratio  of  Unweighted  to  Weighted  Tons  of  Rolled  and  Finished  Products. 

Charts 

Chart  1 — Total  Costs  (Unadjusted)  and  Volume  of  Business. 

Chart  2— Taxes  and  Volume  of  Business. 

Chart  3— Depletion  and  Depreciation  Related  to  Volume  of  Business. 

Chart  4 — Payrolls  Adjusted  to  1938  Wage  Rates  and  Related  to  Volume  of  Business. 

Chart  5— Total  Costs  Adjusted  to  1938  Interest,  Tax,  Pension  and  Wage  Rates  and  1938  Price  Levels,  but 
Unadjusted  for  Changed  Operating  Conditions.  Related  to  Volume  of  Business. 

Chart  6— Percentage  Deviations  from  Average— Total  Costs  Adjusted  to  1938  Interest,  Tax,  Pension  and 
Wage  Rates  and  1938  Price  Level  but  Unadjusted  for  Changed  Operating  Conditions. 

Chart  7 — Relationship  between  Total  Costs  and  Volume  of  Business— 1938  Conditions. 

Chart  8— Percentage  Deviations  from  Average — Payrolls  Adjusted  to  1938  Wage  Rates. 

Chart  9— Payrolls,  Adjusted  to  1938  Conditions,  Related  to  Volume  of  Business. 

Chart  10— "Other  Expenses"  Adjusted  to  1938  Price  Level  and  Related  to  Volume  of  Business. 

Chart  11 — Percentage  Deviations  from  Average — "Other  Expenses",  Adjusted  for  Price  Changes. 

Chart  12 — "Other  Expenses"  Adjusted  for  Changes  in  Commodity  Prices  and  for  Changed  Operating 
Conditions,  Related  to  Volume  of  Business. 

Chart  13— Composition  of  Total  Costs  in  Relation  to  Volume  of  Business. 

Chart  14 — Transportation  and  Miscellaneous  Revenues  Related  to  Shipments. 

Chart  15— Estimated  Additions  to  1938  Deficit— How  Deficit  Would  Have  Increased  if  Prices  Had  Been 
Reduced  and  Volume  Had  Increased  to  Same  Relative  Extent. 

Chart  16— Relation  Between  Sales  and  Costs— Effect  of  Reduction  from  Average  1938  Prices. 

Chart  17— Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Various  Decreases  in  Average  1938  Prices- 
Compared  to  Probable  Resulting  Increases. 

Chart  18— Relation  Between  Sales  and  Costs  Effect  of  Reduction  from  Second  HaK  of  1938  Prices. 

Chart  19 — Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Various  Decreases  in  Price  Prevailing  in  the 
Second  Half  of  1938 — Compared  to  Probable  Resulting  Increases. 

Chart  20— Relation  of  Actual  Tons  of  Rolled  and  Finished  Steel  Products  Shipped  and  Weighted  Tons  of 
All  Tonnage  Products  Shipped. 

Chart  21— Ratio  of  Tons  of  Rolled  and  Finished  Products  to  Weighted  Tons  of  All  Tonnage  Products  at 
Different  Rolled  and  Finished  Shipment  Levels. 

Chart  22 — Per  Cent  of  Weighted  Tons  of  Rolled  and  Finished  Products  Shipped  Represented  by  Un- 
weighted Tonnages  of  Rolled  and  Finished  Products  Shipped. 

I.  Purpose  of  the  Study 

The  success  of  mass  produi^tion  methods  in  American  industrial  practice  has 
given  much  emphasis,  to  the  importance  of  volume  in  reducing  costs.  Failure  to 
appreciate,  in  the  case  of  the  steel  industry,  the  limitations  of  the  extent  to  which 
increased  volume  means  reduced  costs  per  unit  of  product  has  frequently  been 
made  the  basis  of  the  charge  that  steel  prices  are  higher  than  they  should  be  and 
that  the  absence  of  price  competition,  rather  than  the  limitation  imposed  by  costs, 
is  the  reason  why  steel  prices  are  not  lower  than  they  are.  It  is  further  said 
that  if  steel  prices  were  lowered  in  times  of  recession  more  steel  would  be  sold 
and  payrolls  and  employment  would  be  better  maintained.  The  fact  of  the  matter 
is  that  steel  prices  are  not  high.  In  recent  years  they  have  barely  covered  costs. 
This  is  evidenced  by  the  fact  that  in  the  last  ten  years,  1929  to  1938,  the  United 
States  Steel  Corporation  realized  a  return  of  only  1.91%  on  the  combined  invest- 
ment of  the  bondholders  and  stockholders.  From  1930  to  1938  the  rate  of  return 
averaged  less  than  1%  per  year. 

However,  the  contention  that  steel  prices  are  too  high  is  not  made  in  ignorance 
of  the  small  margin  of  profit  currently  being  realized  on  sales.     The  theorj-  of 


14034 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


those  who  would  lower  steel  prices  is  that  such  reductions  greatly  stimulate  sales 
and  that  volume  and  costs  are  so  inter-related  in  the  production  of  steel  that,  on 
the  mass  production  principle,  the  cost  per  ton  would  be  drastically  reduced  if 
volume  were  increased.  Hence,  it  is  argued  that  if  prices  were  reduced,  volume 
would  be  stimulated  to  a  point  where  costs  would  drop  sufficiently  to  make  steel 
production  profitable  at  the  reduced  prices.  It  has  been  the  purpose  of  this 
study  to  ascertain  the  increases  in  volume  that  would  have  to  take  place  to  offset 
various  decreases  in  steel  prices  by  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  sub- 
sidiaries, taking  into  consideration  the  effect  of  increased  volume  on  costs,  and  to 
estimate  the  financial  gain  or  loss  which  would  result  from  price  reductions. 

II.  Summary  of  Findings 

1.  The  total  annual  costs  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  its  sub- 
sidiaries may  be  divided  into  (1)  those  which  must  be  met  regardless  of  the  ton- 
nage of  steel  produced  and  (2)  the  additional  costs  of  producing  each  additional 
ton  of  product.  Taking  the  coats  shown  by  the  profit  and  loss  statements  of  the 
Corporation  from  1927  to  1938  and  adjusting  to  1938  wage,  interest,  and  tax  rates, 
and  to  1938  prices  and  other  operating  conditions,  this  study  shows  that  under 
1938  conditions  the  costs  of  the  first  or  fixed  type  amount  to  $182,100,000  per  year 
while  those  of  the  second  type,  the  additional  costs,  are  approximately  $55.73  per 
weighted  ton  of  product  shipped.'  Thus  the  total  costs  for  any  volume  of  busi- 
ness at  1938  wage,  interest,  and  tax  rates,  and  1938  material  prices,  may  be 
estimated  by  multiplying  the  weighted  tons  shipped  by  $55.73  and  adding 
$182,100,000  to  the  result.  It  should  be  noted,  however,  that  while  these  costs 
are  exclusive  of  all  non-operating  income  and  expense,  they  cover  all  operations 
of  the  Corporation's  subsidiaries  and  hence  do  not  represent  merely  the  cost  of 
producing  steel.  Furthermore,  even  weighted  lonnages  shipped  do  not  reflect  the 
full  volume  of  business,  since  some  goods  and  services  are  sold  by  the  Corpora- 
tion's subsidiaries  which  are  not  measured  in  tons.  Nevertheless,  the  other 
operations  rise  and  fall  with  increases  and  decreases  in  shipments  of  products  to  a 
sufficient  extent  that  the  total  costs  maintain  approximately  the  relationship  to 
shipments  just  described. 

2.  Within  the  range  of  actual  experience  the  additional  costs,  at  1938  wage  and 
tax  rates  and  1938  material  prices,  arising  with  the  shipment  of  each  additional 
ton  remain  constant  at  $55.73.  This  is  true  when  production  averages  as  high  as 
90.4%  and  as  low  as  17.7%  of  ingot  capacity  for  the  entire  year.  While  the  addi- 
tional costs  per  ton  tend  to  remain  constant,  the  average  costs  per  ton  decrease 
as  the  volume  of  shipments  rises  since  the  fixed  costs  of  $182,100,000  are  spread 
over  a  greater  number  of  tons. 

3.  An  approximation  of  the  elements  composing  the  total  costs  of  the  United 
States  Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  is  shown  below: 


Table  1. 


-Elements  of  Total  Costs  1938  Conditions — United  States  Steel  Corpora- 
tion and  Subsidiaries 


Item 

Costs  that  must 
be  met  regard- 
less of  operat- 
ing rate 

Additional 
cost  for  each 

additional 
ton  '  of 
product 
shipped 

Interest - 

$8, 300, 000 
7,  700, 000 

24, 200,  000 

62, 100,.000 
2,500,000 

47,800,000 

$0.00 

0.00 

Taxes  other  than  Social  Security  and  Federal  Income 

1.43 

PayroU 

29.10 

1.16 

nt.hPT  r.axh  jr.rptmfPtt 

21.67 

Total  Cash  Costs _ 

Depreciation  and  Depletion 

152,  600, 000 
29, 500, 000 

53.36 
2.37 

Total  costs                                           .             

$182,100,000 

$55.73 

'  Tonnage  weighted  to  adjust  for  variation  from  normal  proprotions;of  high  and  low  cost  products  and  for 
shipments  of  products  other  than  steel. 

■  By  weighted  tons  are  meant  tonnages  of  each  type  of  product  shipped  (except  cement  and  certain  liquid 
and  gaieous  coke-oven-by-products),  converted,  on  an  average  mill  cost  basis,  to  equivalent  tons  of  average 
cost  rolled  and  finished  steel  products.  In  this  way  adjustment  is  made  for  (1)  variaticns  in  the  types  o' 
steel  products  constituting  the  total  shipments  and  (2)  shipments  of  products  other  then  steel. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14035 


4.  The  elasticity  of  demand  for  a  product  is  measured  by  the  ratio  of  the 
relative  resulting  increase  in  volume  to  the  relative  decrease  in  price.  Assuming 
that,  as  all  analyses  indicate,  steel  has  an  elasticity  of  demand  no  greater  than  1, 
and  that  competitive  meeting  of  prices  would  prevent  increased  participation  in 
the  going  volume  of  business,  the  relative  increase  in  shipments  attributable  to  a 
price  reduction  by  the  Corporation  would  not  be  greater  than  the  relative  decrease 
in  prices,  and  the  total  sales  in  dollars  would  not  be  increased.  Under  these 
circumstances,  the  smallest  general  drop  in  steel  prices  that  could  possibly  have 
raised  the  1938  volume  of  steel  sold  to  1937  levels  would  have  been  40.9%.  A 
price  reduction  of  this  proportion,  even  if  successful  in  restoring  1937  volume, 
would  have  resulted  in  a  cash  loss  for  the  year  of  $219,920,000  and  a  total  loss  to 
the  Corporation,  including  depreciation  and  depletion,  of  $280,704,000.  Such  a 
cash  loss,  if  continued,  would  have  exhausted  the  average  1938  working  capital 
in  less  than  two  years  and  annual  total  losses  on  this  scale  would  wipe  out  the 
entire  equity  of  preferred  and  common  stockholders  existing  on  December  31,  1938 
in  about  four  and  a  half  years. 

5.  Any  reduction  in  steel  prices  below  the  average  prices  prevailing  in  1938 
would  have  served  only  to  increase  the  1938  deficit  of  the  Corporation  which 
amounted  to  $8,758,572,  exclusive  of  non-operating  income  and  expense.  Even 
if  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  is  assumed  to  be  as  high  as  1,  the  estimated 
additions  to  the  1938  deficit  which  would  have  resulted  from  various  price  re- 
ductions would  have  been  as  follows: 


Table  2. — Estimated  Additions  to  19S8  Deficit — How  Deficit  Would  Have  Increased 
if  Prices  Had  Been  Reduced  and  Volume  Had  Increased  to  Same  Relative  Extent — 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Reduction  in  average  price 

Estimated  addi- 
tion to  deficit 

Reduction  in  average  price 

Estimated  ad- 
dition to  deficit 

$3, 900. 000 
20,  500, 000 
43,300,000 

15% 

$68,700,000 
97,400,000 

cm 

20% ::...:::::..:.:. 

IW 

6.  Because  of  the  low  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel,  the  increase  in  volume 
resulting  from  a  reduction  in  price  is  certain  to  be  less  than  the  increase  needed 
to  ofifeet  the  adverse  effects  of  the  lower  price  on  profits.  Regardless  of  the  volume 
of  operations  taken  as  a  starting. point,  the  percentage  increases  in  volume  neces- 
sary to  compensate  for  various  percentage  reductions  in  the  average  1938  prices, 
so  that  profits  or  losses  would  neither  be  increased  or  decreased  by  the  price 
reduction,  are  as  shown  below.  Also  shown  are  the  percentage  increases  in 
volume  which  would  result  if  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  were  as  high  as  1. 

Table  3. — Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compenstate  for  Decreases  in  Average 
19S8  Prices,  Compared  to  Maximum  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume — 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Reduction  in  price 

Increase  in 
volume  re- 
quired to  oflE- 
set  price 
decrease 

Greatest 
probable  re- 
sulting in- 
crease in 
volume 

Reduction  in  price 

Increase  in 
volume  re- 
quired to  off- 
set price 
decrease 

Greatest 
probable  re- 
sulting in- 
crease in 
volupae 

1%  

19!  6% 
48.8% 

M 

15% 

96.  7% 
190. 3% 

17.  7% 
25.0% 

5% 

20% 

10% 

7.  At  average  prices  prevaihng  in  the  second  half  of  1938,  subsequent  to  the 
June  24,  1938  price  reduction,  the  percentage  increases  in  volume  required  to 
offset  further  price  reductions  would  be  even  higher. 


14036        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  4. — Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Decreases  in  2nd  Half 
1938  Prices,  Compared  to  Maximum  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume — 
United  Slates  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Reductioa  in  price 

Increase  in 
volume  re- 
quired to 
offset  price 
decrease 

Greatest 
probable 
resulting 
increase  in 
volume 

Reduction  in  price 

Increase  in 
volume  re- 
quired to 
offset  price 
decrease 

Greatest 
probable 
resulting 
increase  in 
volume 

24^0% 
63.1% 

1.0% 
5.3% 
11. 1% 

138.4% 
342.  6% 

17.7% 

w 

2Qcy 

25.0% 

,/fc 

8.  No  percentage  of  capacity  as  ordinarily  computed  can  be  named  as  the 
break-even  point  for  any  given  level  of  steel  prices,  since  the  exact  percentage  at 
which  the  Corporation  would  break  even  will  also  depend  upon  the  type  of 
products  composing  the  total  tonnage  sold  and  these  vary  considerably  from  month 
to  month  and  from  year  to  year,  even  when  total  shipments  are  approximately 
the  same.  On  a  weighted  tonnage  basis,  the  break-even  point  for  the  Corporation 
at  prices  prevailing  in  the  second  half  of  1938  would  be  at  about  ten  and  a  half 
miUion  weighted  tons.  Depending  on  the  type  of  products  sold,  this  weighted 
tonnage  would  be  equivalent  to  from  50%  to  55%  of  capacity. 

9.  If  prices  were  reduced  to  the  point  where  the  Corporation  would  break  even 
only  if  operations  averr.ged  around  90%  of  capacity,  which  some  critics  have 
suggested  as  the  proper  break-even  point,  the  Corporation  would  have  to  operate 
at  the  impossible  annual  rate  of  130%  of  capacity  to  make  a  5%  return  on  its 
investment  in  tangible  assets. 

III.  Costs  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  in  Relation  to  Volume 

Costs  must  of  necessity  fall  into  one  of  two  categories.  Some  items  of  cost  are 
the  same  regardless  of  the  amount  of  steel  and  other  products  produced  providing 
tlvere  is  not  a  complete  shutdown.  These  costs  are  known  as  "fixed  costs"  or 
"overhead  costs".  There  are  other  items  of  cost  termed  "variable  costs"  or 
"incremental  costs"  or  "additional  costs"  which  are  not  the  same  regardless  of 
volume  but  increase  with  increases  in  the  vc-ame  of  steel  produced  and  sold. 
These  costs  can  be  diminished  by  cutting  down  the  production  of  steel.  The 
fixed  costs,  on  the  other  hand,  cannot  be  diminished  except  by  complete  shutdown, 
but  they  can  be  spread  over  a  greater  number  of  units  of  products  by  increasing 
production.  Both  the  variable  and  the  fixed  costs  are  composed  both  of  costs 
which  embrace  current  cash  outlays,  and  of  depreciation  and  depletion,  which 
do  not. 

The  cost  pattern  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries, 
set  forth  in  the  summary  of  findings  in  Section  II  above,  has  been  derived  from 
the  profit  and  loss  statements  of  the  Corporation  as  set  forth  in  a  financial  report 
covering  the  years  1917  to  1937,  submitted  to  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  on 
February  17,  1939,  in  connection  with  the  Commission's  studies  relative  to  the 
Temporary  National  Economic  Committee.  A  profit  and  loss  statement  for  1938 
on  a  comparable  basis  was  prepared  by  the  Comptroller's  Department  of  the 
Corporation.  These  profit  and  loss  statements  are  basically  the  same  as  those 
contained  in  the  annual  reports  of  the  Corporation,  except  that  some  of  the  items 
have  been  reclassified  in  order  to  render  all  of  the  yearly  statements  comparable 
and  to  comply  with  certain  requests  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission.  Only 
the  figures  from  1927  onward  were  used  in  this  study  because  the  data  for  making 
the  necessary  adjustments  were  not  available  for  prior  years. 

The  total  operating  costs  as  shown  on  the  profit  and  loss  statements  referred 
to  consist  of  the  cost  of  goods  sold  and  operating  exj^enses  of  transportation  and 
other  incidental  operations,  plus  the  selling,  general  and  administrative  expenses, 
and  taxes  other  than  Federal  income  and  profits,  plus  proNisions  for  depreciatitJn 
and  depletion.  To  the  total  of  these  operating  costs  was  added  the  ai.iount  of  the 
idle  plant  expenses,  and  from  t.iat  total  was  subtracted  the  amount  of  the  dis- 
counts from  purchases.  These  last  two  items  were  classified  in  the  report  under 
"Other  Income  Deductions"  and  "Other  Income,"  respectively,  but  it  was  felt 
that  they  were  sufficiently  connected  with  operations  to  be  included  in  thv.  oper- 
ating costs  for  the  purpose  of  this  study.  Also  added  in  was  the  amount  of  the 
interest  on  bonds,  mortgages  and  other  long-ieriu  debt.      Items  classified  under 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        14037 

"Other  Income"  and  "Other  Income  Deductions,"  with  the  exception  of  the  idle 
plant  expenses  and  purchase  discount*,  were  considered  to  be  extraneous  non- 
operating  income  and  expense  and  were  not  included  in  the  computation.  Federal 
income  and  profits  taxes  were  excluded  for  a  different  reason.  These  taxes  are 
dependent  on  profits,  not  on  costs  or  volume  of  business,  and  hence  will  differ 
with  different  prices  that  may  prevail.  Since  the  purpose  of  this  study  was  to 
chart  a  cost  curve  which  could  be  related  to  estimated  sales  and  revenues  at 
various  price  levels,  these  profits  taxes  have  been  omitted  from  the  costs  and  any 
profits  or  losses  shown  in  this  study  are  before  provision  for  Federal  income  and 
profits  taxes.  The  various  components  of  total  costs,  as  extracted  from  the 
above  mentioned  report,  are  shown  in  columns  2,  3,  4  and  5  of  Table  5. 

Table  5. — Compilation  of  Total  Costs  Exclusive  of  Inter-Company  Items  and  Costs 
Connected  with  Extraneous  Transactions  ' — United  States  Steel  Corporation  and 
Subsidiaries 


(l) 

Year 

(2) 

Operating 
Costs  2 

(3) 

Add:  Idle 

Plant 
Expenses 

(4) 

Less:  Pur- 
chase Dis- 
counts 

(5) 

Add:  Bond 
Interest 

(6) 

Less:  Esti- 
mated Inter- 
Company 
Transactions 
(Table  6) 

(7) 

Total  Costs 
After  Elimi- 
nation of 

Inter-Com- 
pany Items  3 

1927 

1,211,837,563 

1,  246,  408,  662 

1,  298,  859,  622 

1,  078,  516,  167 

733,  392, 971 

424,  275,  927 

557,  631,  125 

606,  196,  210 

769,  564,  100- 

1,035,128,989 

1,269,970,378 

765,  723,  200 

1,  822, 861 

2,  550, 146 

1,  679,  794 

2,  516,  129 
2, 904, 457 

3,  084,  823 
3,160,905 

,2,694,390 
2,  089,  259 

1,  396, 989 
1,136,149 

2,  440,  185 

1, 000, 490 
909,916 

1,153;  639 
831,  634 
275,  219 
525,  447 
716,  245 
939,  641 
1,  455,  169 
1,  815,  869 
993,  387 

26,063,504 
25,  746,  009 
14,  944, 870 
5,  640,  096 
5,  469,  624 
5,313,461 
5,  164,  453 
5,051,052 
4,  959,  780 
4,918,431 
5, 141,  088 
8,  262,  327 

371,  721,  399 
389,  268,  104 
434,  445,  063 
360,  637,  726 
201,  536,  082 
71,  173,  131 
150, 992,  224 
170,  362,  492 
236,439,013 
308,  210,  336 
373,  94?,  630 
160,  898,  7:3 

1928 

884  526  797 

1929 

880  055  337 

1930 

724  881  027 

1931 

1932     

539,  399,  336 

1933 - 

1934 

1935. 

539,  234,  485 

1936 _ 

1937.. ._ 

1938-- -- 

731,778,904 
900,  484,  116 
614,  533,  572 

Total 

10,  997,  504,  914 

27,  476, 087 

11,  600,  542 

116,  674,  695 

3,  229,  631,  953 

7,900,423,201 

'  The  figures  herein  contained,  except  the  estimated  inter-company  items,  have  been  taken  from  the 
consolidated  profit  and  loss  statements  submitted  to  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  on  2/17/39.  The 
figures  are  reconcilable  with  those  appearing  in  the  Annual  Reports,  but  are  not  exactly  the  same,  as  some 
reclassification  was  necessary  in  order  to  comply  with  the  Commission's  request  and  also  to  put  the  state- 
ments for  all  years  on  a  comparable  basis. 

2  As  per  statement  to  Federal  Trade  Commission  consists  of  (1)  cost  of  goods  sold  and  operating  expenses 
of  transportation  and  other  incidental  operations;  (2)  selling,  general  administrative  expenses,  and  taxes 
other  f  an  Federal  income  and  profits  taxes;  (3)  provisions  for  depre'  iation  and  depletion.  Additions  to 
bond  sinking  fund  reserve  are  included  in  depreciation  in  1927  and  1928. 

'  Excluding  income  and  expense  connected  with  non-operating  transactions. 

The  costs  that  would  be  obtained  by  adding  together  these  components,  how- 
ever, would  involve  a  certain  amount  of  duplication,  for  on  the  profit  and  loss 
statements  both  the  sales  and  revenues  and  the  cost  of  goods  sold  and  operating 
expenses  of  transportation  and  miscellaneous  operations  include  transactions 
between  the  subsidiary  companies  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation.  Since 
the  inter-company  sales  of  any  one  company  constitute  the  costs  of  the  other, 
and  since  inter-ccmpany  profits  are  eliminated  from  inventory  valuations  in 
making  inventory  adjustments,  both  costs  and  sales  and  revenues  are  inflated, 
from  a  consolidated  viewpoint,  by  the  amount  of  the  inter-company  items,  but 
the  profit  shown  is  unaffected  by  this  method  of  handling.^  These  inter-company 
transactions  are  segregated  in  the  accounts  of  the  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries 
and  in  the  annual  reports  so  far  as  the  sales  of  products  and  some  of  the  miscel- 
laneous operations  are  concerned,  but  the  accounting  systems  of  the  common 
carrier  transportation  companies  make  no  provision  for  this  segregation.  Con- 
sequently, the  inter-company  business  done  by  the  common  carrier  transportation 
companies  must  be  estimated.  Estimates  of  the  net  sales  and  operating  revenues 
with  all  of  the  inter-company  items  eliminated  had  already  been  prepared  by  the 
Comptroller's  Department  of  the  Corporation.  By  subtracting  these  net  sales 
and  operating  revenues  derived  from  outside  sources  from  the  total  of  net  sales 
and  operating  revenues  shown  in  tlie  profit  and  loss  statements  submitted  to  the 
Federal  Trade  Commission,  the  estimated  amount  of  all  inter-company  items  was 

'  See  Appendix  VTT  for  illustration  and  more  complete  discussion. 


14038 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


ascertained.  This  computation  is  shown  in  Table  6.  Since  the  relationship 
between  the  physical  volume  of  outside  business  and  the  cost  of  doing  all  outside 
business  was  what  was  desired,  the  inter-company  items  had  to  be  deducted  from 
the  costs  which  were  taken  from  the  report  ot  the  Federal  Trade  Commission. 
The  deduction  of  the  inter-company  items  estimated  in  Table  6  is  made  in  column 
6  of  Table  5.  Column  7  of  Table  5  shows  the  total  operating  costs  on  an  integrated 
basis  for  each  of  the  years  1927  to  1938. 


Table 


-Estimate  of  Inter-Company  Transactions- 
tion  and  Subsidiaries 


■United  States  Steel  Corpor 


Year 

Net  Sales  and 
Operating 
Revenues ' 

Net  Sales  and 

Operating 

Revenues  less 

Inter-Company 

Items  3 

Estimated 

Inter-Company 

Items 

1927                           ..        - - 

1,318,334,399 

1,381,843,104 

1,502,211,063 

1,175,046,726 

725,248,082 

354,693,131 

521,943,224 

588,835,492 

776,348,013 

1,099,931,336 

1,395,649,630 

766, 673,  763 

946, 613, 000 
992,  575, 000 

1,067,766,000 
814, 409, 000 
523, 712, 000 
283, 520, 000 
370,  951,  000 
418,473,000 
539,  909,  000 
791,721,000 

1,021,602,000 
605,775,000 

371,721,399 

1928                       -.           --                      

389, 268, 104 

1929 

434,  445, 063 

1930     - -.  .. 

360, 637, 726 

150,  992,  224 

170,362,492 

1935 - - — 

236, 439. 013 

1936  .. 

308,210,336 

1937  - 

373, 947,  630 

1938 - 

160,898,753 

Totals      .          

11, 606, 657, 953 

8, 377, 026, 000 

3, 229,  631, 953 

1  As  per  Statement  to  Federal  Trade  Commission,  2/17/39. 

'  As  per  data  prepared  by  Comptroller's  Department  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation— Does  not  include 
Miscellaneous  Non-Operating  Income. 

To  ascertain  the  relationship  between  costs  and  volume,  it  was  necessary  to 
compare  the  above  costs  with  the  related  volume  figures.  Since  the  cost  figures 
were  obtained  from  the  profit  and  loss  statements,  they  represent  the  cost  of  goods 
sold  rather  than  the  cost  of  goods  manufactured  and  hence  are  comparable  with 
the  number  of  tons  shipped  each  year  rather  than  with  the  number  of  tons  pro- 
duced. In  relating  costs  to  shipments,  however,  it  is  necessary  to  make  some 
adjustment  for  changes  in  the  proportions  of  high  and  low  cost  products  constitut- 
ing the  total.  For  instance,  if  the  shipment  figures  showed  that  in  each  of  two 
years  10,000,000  tons  had  been  shipped,  the  total  costs  would  be  greater  in  the 
year  in  which  costly  products,  such  as  sheets  and  tin  plate,  constituted  most  of 
the  tonnage  than  in  the  year  when  lower  cost  products,  such  as  rails  and  heavy 
plates,  predominated.  Adjustment  for  such  a  condition  has  been  made  by  letting 
each  ton  of  rolled  and  finished  steel  product  which  is  of  a  type  whose  1933-1937 
average  mill  cost  was  less  than  the  average  cost  of  all  rolled  and  finished  steel 
products,  count  proportionately  less  than -a  full  ton,  while  tons  of  products  of  a 
class  which  is  on  the  .average  more  costly  than  the  average  cost  of  rolled  and 
finished  steel  products,  have  been  made  to  count  proportionately  more  than  a 
full  ton.  By  weighting  in  this  way  the  number  of  tons  of  all  tonnage  products 
shipped  each  year  has  been  converted  into  eguivalent  tons  of  average  cost  rolled 
and  finished  steel  products.'  Thus  in  any  years  in  which  the  1933-1937  average 
proportions  of  high  and  low  cost  products  were  sold  the  actual  tonnage  is  the  same 
as  the  weighted  tonnage,  while  the  total  tonnage  for  years  having  an  abnormal 
proportion  of  high  or  low  cost  products  has  been  converted  to  a  tonnage  figure 
that  is  comparable  to  the  normal  years  from  a  cost  standpoint.  By  a  similar 
weighting  process,  the  total  tonnage  of  rolled  and  finished  products  shipped  has 
been  further  adjusted  to  include  the  equivalent  tons  of  steel  represented  by  the 
products  other  than  steel  which  are  sold  on  a  tonnage  basis  by  the  Corporation's 
subsidiaries. 


•  The  total  tons  shipped  are  gross  tons  except  with  respect  to  a  few  products  Included  on  a  net  tonnage 
lasls,  and  the  average  cost  per  ton  is  the  a^irage  for  this  mixed  tonnage. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14039 


Table  7. — Total  Costs  (Unadjusted)  and  Volume  of  Business — United  States  Steel 
Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Year 

Total  Costs 
(Table  5) 

Millions  of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Product? 
Shipped 

Year 

Total  Costs 
(Table  5) 

Millions  of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 
Shipped 

$867,002,039 
884.526,797 
880,055.337 
724.881.027 
539,399.338 
361,225,861 

13.0 
14.0 
15.1 
U.9 
8.1 
4.4 

1933 

$414,438,812 
442,862,915 
539,234,485 
731,778,904 
900,484,116 
614.-533,672 

6.2 

1928 

1934  .         

6.1 

7.6 

1930 

1936 

11.0 

13.2 

1938 

7.8 

In  Tabl^  7  the  total  costs  as  shown  in  Table  5  are  compared  with  the  weighted 
tons  of  all  products  shipped.  In  Chart  1  these  costs  are  plotted  in  relation  to  the 
weighted  tons  shipped.     It  is  apparent  from  this  chart  that  there  is  a  close  rela- 


Chart 

1 

TOTAL  COSTS  (UNADJUSTED)  AND  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS 

U.  a  STEa  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

1100 

°  8  8  8  i  8  8  8  8   8  i  i  ^ 

MILLIONS    OF    DOLLARS 

\ 

,, 

'''' 

1  ^ 

g     ^ 

Q     700 

o     600 
-     500 

2  400 

200 

100 

0 

\ 

1937 

y 

1927 

mi 

IK^!* 

1936 

.'' 

1930 

"? 

,^ 

■'' 

' 

y. 

ilwi 

1»3J 

'.w'i 

"l 

?»'' 

■' 

( 

HOTt:  COSTS** 

J      1      2      3     4      5     6     7      8      9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16    17    1 
MIUJONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

E  una  80ND  INTtREST.  BUT  BEfORE  fEOtRM.  JNCOME  TM  *ND  EXCLUSI'/t  OF  NON-OPERATING  ITEMS  »N0  INTER-COMPA 

8 

NY  TIWNSACTIONS 

tionship  between  total  costs  and  tonnages  shipped  and  that  this  relationship  is 
of  such  a  nature  that  it  appears  as  a  straight  line  in  the  graph.  Fitting  a  straight 
line  in  such  a.  way  that  the  sum  of  the  squares  of  the  vertical  deviations  of  each 
of  the  points  from  the  line  is  at  a  minimum,  it  appears  that  the  average  relation- 
ship between  costs  and  volume  for  the  period  1927  to  1938  was  such  that  the  total 
costs  consisted  of  $54.51  per  ton  sold,  plus  fixed  costs  of  $120,530,000.  However, 
this  relationship  represents  the  relation  prevailing  on  the  average  under  all  the 
changing  conditions  that  took  place  between  1927  and  1938.  An  inspection  of 
the  chart  reveals  clearly  that  the  costs  in  the  earher  years  were  generally  lower 
than  average,  while  in  the  later  years  they  have  been  above  this  average.  This 
shows  that  the  present-day  costs  of -producing  steel  are  higher  than  they  formerly 
were.  To  ascertain  what  the  relationship  between  cost  and  volume  would  be 
under  1938  conditions  it  was  necessary  to  adjust  the  cost  figures  for  each  of  the 
prior  years  for  changes  in  interest,  tax  and  wage  rates,  material  prices,  and  other 
conditions  that  have  since  taken  place. 

Since  different  changes  have  taken  place  in  the  various  types  of  expenses,  the 
first  step  in  attempting  an  adjustment  of  the  data  to  1938  conditions  v.as  to  break 
down  the  total  costs  into  their  principal  components.  Table  8  gives  this  break- 
down.    The  components  shown  are  (1)  taxes  other  than  Federal  income  and  profits 


14040 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


taxes  and  social  security  taxes,  (2)  interest,  (3)  depreciation  and  depletion,  (4) 
payroll,  (5)  pensions,  (6)  social  security  taxes,  and  (7)  other  expenses.  Payroll 
figures  do  not  exactly  reflect  the  salary  and  wage  cost  in  the  goods  sold  because 
some  payroll  goes  into  inventory  and  some  of  the  goods  sold  are  taken  from  the 
previous  year's  inventory.  To  the  extent  that  payroll  is  more  or  less  than  the 
wage  and  salary  cost  in  goods  sold  in  any  particular  year  because  of  production 
exceeding  or  being  less  than  shipments,  the  "other  expense"  component  is  under- 
stated or  overstated.  The  amount  of  inventory  fluctuation  is  relatively  small, 
however,  and  the  effect  on  the  ultimate  cost  computation  is  negligible.  With 
the  breakdown  of  costs  computed,  the  adjustments  applied  to  each  component 
must  be  considered. 

Two  of  the  components,  interest  and  pensions,  are  in  no  way  dependent  upon 
the  volume  of  business  performed.  These  items  are  completely  fixed.  Hence, 
to  convert  to  1938  conditions,  all  that  had  to  be  done  was  to  substitute  in  each 
year  the  1938  amount  of  interest  and  pensions  paid. 

Tablk   8. — Analysis   of  Operating    Costs   Into    Components — United  States   Steel 
Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Taxes 

Other 

Total  Costs 

than 

Deprecia- 
tion and 
Deple- 
tion' 

Year 

Before  In- 
come Taxes 
as  per 

Federal 
Income 
and  Prof- 

Interest 

Payroll ' 

Pensions' 

Social  Se- 
curity 
Taxes 

Other  E\- 
penscs 

Table  6 

its  Taxes 

and  Social 

Security ' 

1927 

867, 002, 039 

34,817,116 

26,  063.  504 

58, 906, 007 

410,  289, 135 

2,414.226 

334,512,051 

36, 015, 942 
37,  739,  322 

2, 924,  879 

352,  602, 172 

1929 

880,055.  .37 

14, 944,  870 

63,  274. 163 

406,  886,  492 

3,354,504 

353, 855. 986 

1930 

724,881  J27 

« 36,  047,  026 

5,  640,  096 

58,  550, 120 

367,  945,  736 

3,  772,  053 

2.52,925,996 

1931 

5.39,  399,  336 

33, 162,  707 

5,  469,  624 

47,  317,  895 

253, 178,  649 

5.  241,  466 

195.  028.  995 

1932 

361,  225,  861 

31,943,315 

5,  313,  461 

40,  319,  794 

131,602,678 

6,904,978 

145,141,635 

:933 

414,438.812 

33,  288,  485 

5,164,453 

43,  584,  499 

160,  746,  223 

7, 163,  032 

164,  492, 120 

lb34 

442,  862,  915 

32,  615,  83! 

5,  051,  052 

44,  579,  309 

207,  564, 103 

7,  223,  546 

145,  829,  074 

1935 

539,  234,  485 

»34,691,33C 

4,  959,  780 

47,  801,  389 

246,  508,  043 

7,  362,  723 

197,911.220 

1936 

731,778,904 

37,  999,  606 

4,918,431 

55,  466,  762 

328,  070,  724 

7.642,026 

4, 081,  587 

293,  599,  768 

1937 

900,484,116 

45, 132,  333 

5,141,088 

59,  589, 159 

426,  330,  944 

7,  380,  254 

13,415,904 

343, 494,  434 

1938 

614,  533,  572 

34,  602,  915 

8,  262.  327 

48,  532,  841 

275, 364, 898 

7,  743,  046 

11,309,216 

228, 718, 329 

7,  900,  423,  201 

428,055,928 

116, 674, 695 

635, 159, 241 

3,614,488,117 

69, 126,  733 

28,  806,  707 

3,008,111,780 

1  Total  taxes  as  per  profit  and  loss  statements  in  annual  reports,  less  reserves  for  Federal  income  and  prof- 
its taxes  as  per  report  to  Federal  Trade  Commission  and  social  security  taxes  as  per  profit  and  loi  s  jtatements 
in  annual  reports. 

>  Does  not  include  cost  of  dismantling,  moving  and  rearranging  facilities,  which  is  Included  in  deprecia- 
tion and  depletion  in  the  profit  and  loss  statement  in  the  annual  reports  from  1936  on. 

3  Excluding  construction  payroll. 

*  Excluding  certain  taxes  charged  against  special  income. 

5  As  per  1936  annual  report— iron  ore  taxes  not  segregated  from  other  overhead  in  1935  annual  report 
profit  and  Joss  statements. 

»  Figures  for  1928  to  1938  as  per  annual  reports  and  the  S.  E.  C.  registration  statement.  Form  A-2;  figure 
for  1927  «upplied  by  Comptroller's  Department  of  the  Corporation. 

Since  tax  rates  have  changed  considerably  over  the  period  under  consideration, 
it  is  clear  that  some  adjustment  in  the  tax  figures  was  necessary.  In  Table  9 
the  taxes,  other  than  social  security  and  Federal  income  and  profits  taxes,  are 

Table    9. — Taxes    and    Volume    of    Business — United    Stales    Steel    Corporation 
and  Subsidiaries 


Year 

Taxes  Other 
than  Social 

Security  and 
Federal  In- 
come and 

Profits  Taxes 

Millions   of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 
Shipped 

Year 

Taxes   Other 
than  Social 

Security  and 
Federal  In- 
come and 

Profits  Taxes 

Millions  of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 
Shipped 

34,817,116 
36, 015,  942 
37,  739,  322 
36,  047, 026 
33, 162. 707 
31,943,315 

13.0 
14.0 
15.1 
11.9 
8.1 
4.4 

1933  .  ...- 

33,288,485 
32,615,831 
34, 691,  330 
37, 999, 606 
45, 132,  333 
34,602,915 

6.2 

fi.  I 

7.6 

1936 

U.O 

1931 

1937 

13.2 

1932        

1938 

7.8 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14041 


compared  with  the  weighted  tons  of  products  shipped.  The  relationship  be- 
tween taxes  and  volume  was  then  ascertained  by  plotting  taxes  against  shipments 
as  shown  on  Chart  2.  An  inspection  of  the  chart  shows  that  the  points  for  1927 
to  1931  fall  approximately  along  one  line,  while  the  points  for  1932  to  1938  fall 
along  another.  The  simplest  estimate  of  what  the  taxes  would  be  at  various 
rates  of  ojjeration  under  1938  conditions  was  to  compute  the  average  relationship, 
by  the  least  squares  method  referred  to  above,  for  the  period  1932  to  1938. 
It  will  be  noted  that  the  1938  taxes  fall  very  close  to  the  line  and  very  close 
to  the  points  for  other  years  when  volume  was  about  the  same.  Hence  it  is 
evident  that  the  tax  rates  which  affect  the  Corporation  with  regard  to  taxes 
other  than  Federal  income  and  social  secuiity  taxes,  have  not  been  materially 

Chart  2 


TAXES  AND  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

60 

60 

50 

50 

,, 

L — 

5 

40 

__, 

«i 

I'?, 

'nV 

L'?— -. 

a'i-- 



1938      »?. 

•-^       - 

11- 

— 

15*27 

o 

30 



^-^ ' 

19M 

30      o 

^,,-'— 

z 

z 

o 

20 

20     2 

zi 

-J 

z 

10 

10 

0 

0 

C 

)     1     2     3     4     5     6     7     8     9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16   17    18 
MILUONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

NOTt:   TAOS  INaUOE  AU  TAXES  KCtPT  SOCIW.  SECURITY  AND  FtDERAl  (NCWrlE  AHO  fKOrn%  TAXES 

altered  throughout  the  1932-1938  period.  The  taxes  paid  from  1927  to  1931, 
however,  are  clearly  much  below  what  would  be  paid  today  at  the  same  operating 
rates.  For  this  reason  in  this  study  the  actual  taxes  paid  for  each  of  the  years 
1932  to  1938  have  been  used  in  computing  the  estimated  total  costs  under  1938 
conditions,  but  the  taxes  for  the  years  prior  to  1932  have  been  estimated  on  the 
laasis  of  the  average  1932  to  1938  tax-volume  relationship.  This  relationship 
indicates  that  total  taxes,  other  than  Federal  income  and  social  security,  amount 
to  $24,217,000,  plus  $1.43  for  each  weighted  ton  of  product  sold.  The  calcula- 
tion of  the  estimated  taxes  for  the  years  1927  to  1931  is  shown  in  Table  10. 
The  final  estimate  of  the  t;.  <es,  other  than  social  security  and  Federal  income 
taxes,  that  would  be  paid  under  present  tax  laws  at  various  volumes  of  production 
is  shown  in  Table  11. 


14042       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  10. — Estimated  Taxes  (Other  Than  Social  Security  and  Federal  Income)  in 
Prior  Years  if  19S2-19S8  Rates  Had  Prevailed— United  States  Steel  Corporation 
and  Subsidiaries 

[Taxes =$24,21 7,0004-$I.433  per  weighted  ton  shipped  <] 


Year 

Millions  of 

Weighted 

Tons  Shipped 

FiMd  (Mil- 
lions of 
Dollars) 

Variable 

(Millions  of 

Dollars) 

Tota'.  Taxes 

(Millions  of 

Dollars) 

1927 

13.009 
13.994 
15.089 
11. 935 
8.131 

24.217 
24.217 
24.217 
24.217 
24.217 

18.642 
20.053 
21.623 
17. 103 
11.652 

42  859 

1928 

44  270 

1929 

45.840 

1930 

41. 320 

1931                         .    .- 

35. 869 

1 1932-1938  average  relationship  of  taxes  in  relation  to  volume. 

Table  11. — Taxes  and  Volume  of  Business,   Under  Present   Tax  Laws — United 
States  SteeV  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Year 

Taxes  Other 
than  Social 

Security  and 
Federal  In- 
come 

Millions  of 
Weighted 
)Tons  of  Prod- 
ucts Shipped 

Year 

Taxes  Other 
than  Social 

Security  and 
Federal  In- 
come 

Millions  of 

Weighted 

Tons  of  Prod 

ucts  Shipped 

1927 

>  $42, 859, 000 
■  44,  270, 000 
'45,840,000 
•  41, 320. 000 
■35,869.000 
31, 943, 315 

13.0 
14.0 
15.1 
11.9 
8.1 
4.4 

1933 

33, 288, 485 
32, 615, 831 
34,  691,  330 
37,999,606 
45, 132,  333 
34, 602, 916 

6.2 

1928 

1934 .._ 

1935 

6.1 

1929 

7.6 

1936 

11.0 

1931  .  . 

1937 

13.2 

1932. 

1938 

7.8 

'  Amouats  for  years  prior  to  1932  estimated  on  basis  of  1932-1938  average  relationship  between  cost  and 
volume  (see  Table  10). 

On  Chart  3  have  been  plotted  the  depreciation  and  depletion  charges  for  each 
of  the  years  against  the  weighted  tonnage  shipped.  A  computation  of  the  line 
of  average  relationship  by  the  least  squares  method  referred  to  above  shows  that 
the  total  depreciation  and  depletion  charges  have  averaged  $29,500,000,  plus 
$2.37  for  each  weighted  ton  produced.  '  An  inspection  of  the  chart  with  the  line 
drawn  in  shows  that  all  of  the  points  fall  rather  close  to  the  Une  and  deviations 
that  exist  are  more  or  less  at  random  and  do  not  seem  to  be  the  result  of  conditions 
changing  with  the  passage  of  time.  Hence,  the  actual  depreciation  and  depletion 
charges  for  each  year  have  been  used  without  adjustment. 

Table  12. — Adjustment  of  Payroll  to  19S8  Wage  Rates — United  States  Steel  Cor- 
poration and  Subsidiaries 


Year 

PayroU 

Averse 
Hourly 
Earnings 

Ratio  of  1938 

Average  Hourly 

Earnings  to 

Tliose  of  Year 

of  PayroU 

Estimated 

Payroll  at  1938 

Rates 

410,  289, 135 
400.000,492 
406,  886. 492 
367, 945,  736 
253, 178. 649 
131, 602. 678 
160,  746, 223 
207,  564, 103 
246,  508, 043 
328,070,724 
426. 330, 944 
275,  364,  898 

1.682 
.687 

;687 
.691 
.614 
.596 
.705 
.731 
.737 
.864 
.902 

1.3226 
1.3130 
1.  3149 
1.  3130 
r.3054 
1.  4691 
1.  51,34 
1.2794 
1. 2339 
1.2239 
1. 0440 
1.0000 

542,  648, 410 

1928.  - - 

625,  200, 646 

535,015,048 

483,112,751 

1931 

330,  499,  408 

1932 — 

193.  337,  494 

1933 - - 

243.  273.  334 

1934 

265,  557,  613 

1935 

304,  166.  274 

1938 

401.  525,  759 

1937 

445, 089,  506 

1938 

275, 364, 898 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        14043 

Wage  rates  have  increased  considerably  from  the  low  point  of  the  depression 
and  even  from  the  prosperity  year  of  1929.  Hence,  the  need  for  adjustment  of 
the  payroll  figures  to  1938  conditions  is  obvious.  This  adjustment  is  shown  in 
Table  12,  v/here  the  payrolls  for  each  of  the  respective  years  are  multiplied  by  the 
ratio  of  the  1938  average  hourly  earnings  to  the  average  hourly  wage  prevailing 
in  the  year  of  the  payiolls.  Chart  4  shows  the  relation  to  volume  of  the  payrolls 
for  each  of  the  respective  years  adjusted  to  1938  wage  rates.  A  line  of  average 
relationship  has  been  constructed  by  the  least  squares  method.  An  inspection  of 
the  chart  shows  that,  in  general,  payrolls  for  the  later  years  are  lower  than  what 
they  would  have  been  for  the  earlier  years  if  1938  hourly  rates  had  prevailed. 
This  indicates  that,  to  some  extent  at  least,  the  increases  in  hourly  wage  costs 
have  been  offset  by  increased  productivity  per  man  hour.  Adjustment  for  this 
factor  has  been  taken  care  of,  however,  by  the  adjustment  for  long-term  trend 
in  the  cost  volume  relationship  which  will  be  discussed  later. 

Closely  connected  with  the  adjustment  of  payroll  is  the  estimate  of  social 
security 'taxes.     These  taxes  did  not  exist  prior  to  1936,  and  the  rates  have  been 

Chart  3 


DEPLETION  AND  DEPRECIATION  RELATED  TO  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS 
U.  S.  STEEL  COKHUHATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

70 

^      60 

< 

o      50 
o 

-      40 

^      30 
o 

d      20 

s 

10 
0 

1 

1 

70 

60      1 
50      § 
40      fe 
30      1 
20      1 
10 

1928 

^' 

>'l9S9 

'" 

n-R 

- 

,. 

J935 

193_Oj 

-T927 

1937 

'9«,- 

193^ 

1 

r 

']931 

,, 

„,- 

,-' 

''' 

( 

3      1      2      3      4      5      6.     7      8      9     10    11     12    13    14    15    16    17     1 
MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

8 

increasing  since  then.  The  best  method  of  estimating  what  the  social  security 
taxes  would  have  been  for  each  of  the  respective  years  under  1938  conditions 
would  seem  to  be  to  take  the  ratio  of  the  1938  social  security  taxes  to  the  1938 
payroll  and  apply  this  ratio  to  the  adjusted  payroll  figures  for  each  of  the  respec- 
tive years.  In  ascertaining  the  ratio  of  social  security  taxes  to  payroll,  the  total 
payroll,  including  construction  payroll,  has  been  used,  since  the„total  social  security 
tax  paid  is  based  on  the  entire  payroll,  including  that  charged  to  construction  as 
well  as  that  charged  to  operations.  The  pajToll  figures  used  in  the  cost  computa- 
tion, however,  consist  only  of  operating  payroll  and  do  not  include  construction 
payroll,  which  is  properly  treated  on  the  books  of  the  Corporation  as  a  capital 
expenditure.  The  estimated  amount  of  social  security  taxes  for  each  of  the 
respective  payroll  figures  is  shown  in  Table  13. 

The  classification  "other  expenses"  shown  in  the  breakdown  of  total  costs  is 
simply  the  residual  amount  after  deducting  each  of  the  other  components.  It  is 
impossible  to  obtain  a  satisfactory  breakdown  of  this  item  because,  in  order  to 
keep  the  costs  of  different  operations  and  products  properly  segregated,  the 
accounts  of-  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  are  classified  on  an  entirely 


14044  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

different  basis  from  that  used  in  this  study.  "Other  expenses"  does  consist, 
however,  largely  of  goods  and  services  purchased  from  others,  including  freight 
paid  for  transporting  materials,  although  freight  paid  on  shipments  of  finished 
goods  to  customers  is  treated  as  a  deduction  from  sales.  To  some  extent  at  least, 
therefore,  these  expenses J^ave  been  affected  from  year  to  year  by  changes  in  the 
commodity  price  levels. 

Table   13. — Estimate  of  Social  Security  Taxes  at  1938  Rates — United  States  Steel 
Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


1938  Social  Security  Tax  -f-  Total  1938  Payroll '  =  1938  Average  Rate] 
$11,309,216              -^          $282,209,332          =             .040074           J 

Year 

Payroll  at  1938 
Wage  Rates 

Social  Security 

Taxes  at  1938 

Rates 

Year 

Payroll  at  1938 
Wage  Rates 

Social  Security 

Taxes  at  19as 

Rates 

1927 

$542,  648,  410 
525,  200,  646 
.535,015,042 
483,112,751 
330.  499,  408 
193, 337, 494 

$21,  746, 092 
21, 046, 891 
21, 440, 193 
19,  360,  260 
13,  244,  433 
7,  747,  807 

1933... 

1934 _ 

1935 

$243,  273,  334 
265,  557,  513 
304,166,274 
401,  .523,  759 
445,  0S9,  506 
275.  364,  898 

$9  748  932 

1928 

1929 

10,641,952 
12  189  159 

1930 

1936 

"*  1 6,  090  743 

1931 

1937. 

1938 

17  836,517 

1932  . 

11,034,973 

'  Including  Construction  Payroll. 

It  might  be  said  that  no  adjustment  should  be  made  for  the  changing  prices  of 
materials  and  services  purchased  on  the  theory  that  such  prices  are  generally 
loifrer  when  steel  production  is  low  and  higher  in  periods  of  prosperity  when  steel 
production  is  high,  and  that  a  computation  of  the  relation  of  volume  to  cost  should 
include  the  normally  expected  change  in.  material  prices.  However,  it  was  felt 
that  it  was  advisable  to  make  a  broad  general  adju.stment  which  would  roughly 
eliminate  the  effect  of  the  low  prices  wnich  prevailed  in  the  low  volume  years  for 
the  following  reasons: 

1.  The  purpose  of  the  study  is  to  ascertain  the  extent  to  which  a  price  decrease 
as  of  1938  could  be  compensated  for  by  increased  volume  as  distinguished  from 
reducing  wage  rates,  or  having  the  benefit  of  reduced  material  costs,  either  of 
which  would  permit  of  some  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel. 

2.  Comparison  of  the  "other  expenses"  for  1931,  1935  and  1938,  three  j-ears  of 
approximately  similar  volume,  shows  that  under  1938  conditions  prices  of  materials 
did  not  decline  as  much  as  they  formej-ly  did  when  steel  operations  were  low. 

3.  An  arbitrary  reduction  in  steel  prices,  the  advisability  of  which  is  being 
considered  in  this  study,  .would  be  less  likely  to  be  accompanied  bj'  a  decline  in 
material  prices  than  would  a  decline  in  steel  prices  brought  about  by  natural 
economic  forces. 

4.  Adjustment  for  material  price  changes  tends  to  raise  the  cost  figures  for  the 
low  volume  years,  thus  decreasing  the  slope  of  the  total  cost  line  and  increasing 
the  estimate  of  the  extent  to  which  increased  volume  would  decrease  unit  costs. 
Hence,  adjustment  rather  than  nonadjustment  presents  a  case  more  favorable  to 
the  critics  of  steel  prices. 

On  the  other  hand,  since  many  of  the  things  the  Corporation  must  purchase 
did  not  drop  in  price  to  the  same  extent  that  commodities  in  general  did,  overad- 
justment  had  to  be  avoided.  The  basis  of  adju.stment  used  has  been  the  U.  S. 
Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  index  of  wholesale  commodity  prices  other  than  farm 
and  food  products.  In  order  not  to  overadjust,  only  half  of  the  "other  expense" 
items  have  been  adjusted  by  multiplying  them  by  the  ratio  of  the  1938  index  to 
the  index  prevailing  in  the  year  in  which  the  "other  expenses"  were  incurred.  To 
the  half  of  the  "other  expen.ses"  thus  adjusted  has  been  added  the  remaining  half 
without  adjustment.  The  calculation  of  the  adjustment  and  the  final  adjusted 
figures  are  shown  in  Table  14. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chabt  4 


14045 


MILLIONS    OF    DOLLARS                          5 

oissiiii     1 

ADJUSTED  TO  1938  WAGE  RATES  AND  RELATED  TO  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

^,''' 

600 

00 

a. 

500     < 

o 
400     ^ 

o 
300     w 

o 
200    li 

100 
0 

1927 

1928 

,.^'<^ 

^' 

1930 

-''' 

*1937 

,935, 

■93^. 

^'^ 

1936 

^ 

1933 

-" 

"was 

'^ 

0     1      2      3     4      5     6      7     8     9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16    17    18 
MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

NOTE:  CONSTRUCTION  PAYROUS  EXCLUDED 

Table  14. 


'Other  Expenses"  Adjusted  for  Changes  in  Price  Level — United  States 
Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Millions  of 

Weighted  Tons 

of  Products 

Shipped 


4.4. _ 

1932 

6.1 

1934 

6.2 

7.6 

1933 
1935 

7.8- 

8  1 

1931 

11.0 

1936 

11  9 

1930 

13  0 

1927 

13.2 

1937 

14  0 

1928 

15  1 

1929 

Total 

...... 

"Other  Ex- 
penses" Un 
adjusted 


145, 141, 
145, 829, 
164, 492, 
197,911, 
228,  718, 
195, 028, 
293,  599, 
252, 925. 
334,  512, 
343, 494, 
352,  602, 
3,13,  855, 


(Dj 


570. 818 
914,537 
246, 060 
955,610 
359, 165 
514,  498 
799,884 
462, 998 
256,026 
747, 217 
301,086 
927, 993 


,055,i 


(E) 


70.4 

78.4 
71.2 
77.9 
81.7 
75.0 
79.6 
85.2 
94.0 
85.3 
92.9 
91.6 


(F) 


Index  to 
That  of 
Year  of 
Costs 


1.1605 
1.0421 
1. 1475 


1. 0264 
0.9589 
0.  8691 
0.  9578 
0.  8794 


(Q) 


50%  of  Costs 

Adjasted  for 

Price  Change 

(DXF) 


377, 354 
784, 644 
359, 165 
222,  543 
875,  401 
265,  369 
362,  212 
499,  484 
039, 175 
802,  077 


(H) 


Adjusted 

'Other  Ex- 

pen.se" 

(D+Q) 


156,789.252 
148,  898,  776 
176,  623.  414 

202,  740,  254 
228,718,330 

203,  737,  041 
297,  475,  285 
247,  728, 367 
312, 618,  238 
336, 246,  701 
331, 340, 261 
334.  730,  070 

2, 9;i7, 645. 989 


B.  L.  S.  Index  of  Wholesale  Prices— all  commodities  except  food  and  farm  products. 


14046 


CONCENTRATION  QF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


a 

2 

i^sSiSi 

s§IS.sl 

5 

a 

o 

1 

1 

6 

^ 

^■-" 

X 

1 

«     - 

g 

, 

sg^Sisiiigsg 

a 

^ 

ll 

liilSg^'giiii 

«■ 

s 

1 

^ 

§s"§iHi§§s'ii§ 

1 

■1 

« 

>> 

iil§giSiiSi§ 

i" 

11 

^ 

9-" 

t,-o  cTcj  2"«  2  2  S  ^  c3  53 

i 

11 

■§ 

(^ 

1 

i 

si 

isssiiisiiii 

«  2 

1 

a§giiis"H'iiis 

1 

°3 

Ig-gigio-iHisl 

11 

■3g 

11 

gl       »iliiii§iSi§ 

S 

ll 

it 

1? 

2gSsi^lgllSS 

i 

•c5 

'^1 

o  :$  ^"^"«  !j  S  S  S  S  IS  S 

g^ 

o  c 

o-O 

1 

S"5; 

e 

pa 

„  o 

*^  eg 



■SH 

1 

ssssssssssss 

s 

,j 

S 

1 

II 

tC  tC  t~."  h-T  r-"  t-"  J^  t~r  t-^  t-"  t~  t-^ 

w2 

1^ 

1        . 

i 

:-« 

III! 

^u^%m^%%n%% 

oc 

5 

5  w 

II 

miMmmm 

1° 

dH^i^^^^^p^-^ 

1 

fig 

« 

mmmmmm 

111! 

1-1 

a 

00  oo"  oo  00  oo  ao  CO  00  00  oc  CO  00 

§ 

•S 

2S 

^.2ga 

So 

05 

J 

iiiiililliii  'i 

j2 
5 

O 

>- 

-      1 
1 

1^11 

i 

ill! 

"w 

s 

3 

"1 

! 

iiil 

a 

UCQ 

Sa 

nisi 

1 

23 

H 

:   3 

2| 

iffli 

h3 

n 

looioc^P 

;   ^ 

^? 

:"*!?t 

■«"<o<Of-r- 

"^ 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14047 


In  Table  15  the  various  components  of  cost  for  each  of  the  respective  years 
adjusted  to  1938  interest,  tax,  pension  and  wage  rates  and  to  1938  price  levels 
have  been  added  together  to  give  total  cost  figures.  These  total  cost  figures 
represent  what  would  have  been  the  cost  for  the  volume  sold  in  each  of  the 
respective  years  if  1938  conditions  of  wages,  interest,  taxes,  pensions  and  prices 
had  prevailed.  These  total  costs,  however,  do  not  take  into  consideration  the 
long-term  downward  trend  of  costs  in  relation  to  volume  due  to  changes  in 
methods  of  production  within  the  industry  itself  and  hence  do  not  quite  represent 
what  the  cost  would  have  been  if  the  same  volume  had  been  sold  in  1938.  An 
instance  of  this  was  referred  to  in  connection  with  the  adjustment  of  payrolls 
where  it  was  seen  that  the  payrolls  for  earlier  years  would  have  been  greater  in 
relation  to  volume  produced  than  present-day  payrolls  if  present-day  hourly  rates 
were  paid.  Hence  it  became  necessary  to  make  a  further  adjustment  of  total 
costs  for  any  general  increase  in  efficiency  and  other  changes  in  operating  conditions 
that  may  have  taken  place  during  the  period. 

Table  16. — Deviation  of  Adjusted  Total  Costs  '  from  Average  Costs  for  Volume 
Involved — United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Year 

MiUions  of 
Weighted 

Tons  of 
Products 

Shipped 

Actual 

Adjusted 

Costs 

Average 
Adjusted 
Costs  for 
Volume  > 

Deviation 

Deviation 

as  Percent 

age  of 

Average 

Cost 

4.4 
6.1 
6.2 
7.6 
7.8 
8.1 
11.0 
11.9 
13.0 
13.2 
14.0 
15.1 

446.1 
518.3 
,  522.  5 
617.6 
614.3 
646.7 
824.6 
866.1 
994.8 
919.9 
1005. 1 
1016. 3 

429.7 
629.1 
535.0 
616.8 
628.5 
646.1 
81.5.  6 
868.2 
932.5 
944.2 
991.0 
1055.  3 

-1-16.4 
-10.8 
-12.5 
+0.8 
-14.2 
4-0.6 
-(-9.0 
-2.1 
+62.3 
-24.3 
+14.1 
-39.0 

+3.8 

1934 — - - 

-2.0 

1933 — - 

-2.3 

1935                             

+0.1 

1938                         

—2.3 

1931 

+0.1 

1936 

+1.1 

-0.2 

-(-6.7 

-2.6 

1928 

+1  4 

1929 

—3.7 

'  Total  costs  adjusted  to  1938  interest,  tax,  pension,  and  wage  rates  and  to  1938  price  levels. 
•  As  indicated  by  line  of  average  relationship,  Chart  5. 

In  Chart  5  the  total  costs  adjusted  to  1938  interest,  tax,  pension  and  wage  rates 
and  1938  price  levels  are  plotted  against  the  number  of  weighted  tons  shipped. 
The  line  of  average  relationship  computed  by  the  least  squares  method  has  been 
drawn  upon  the  graph.  In  Table  16  have  been  set  forth  the  actual  adjusted  costs 
and  next  to  them  have  been  placed  what  those  total  costs  would  have  amounted  to 
for  the  same  volume  if  they  were  actually  located  on  the  line.  In  the  third  column 
the  deviations  or  difi'erences  between  the  two  are  set  down,  and  in  the  fourth 
column,  the  deviations  are  reduced  to  percentages  of  the  average  cost  for  the 
volume  in  question  as  indicated  by  the  line  of  average  relationship.  These  per- 
centage deviations  are  plotted  by  years  on  Chart  6.  An  inspection  of  this  chart 
will  show  that  many  of  the  deviations  are  more  or  less  at  random,  but  that  to  a 
certain  extent  costs  in  later  years  tend  to  be  lower  than  average,  while  costs  in 
earlier  years  tend  to  be  higher.  This  general  trend,  computed  mathematically 
by  the  least  squares  method,  shows  the  extent  to  which  the  deviations  from  the 
average  are  correlated  with  the  passage  of  timie.  The  computation  shows  that 
costs  tended  to  be  2.17%  above  average  at  the  beginning  of  the  period  and  2.15% 
below  average  at  the  end.  Thus  the  gradual  increase  in  efficiency  in  the  eleven 
years  preceding  1938  has  been  associated  with  a  total  drop  in  costs  roughly  equal 
to  4.32%  of  average  costs.  This  represents  an  average  decrease  in  costs  equal  to 
.393%  of  average  costs  per  years.  Thus,  the  costs  under  1938  conditions  can  be 
estimated  by  subtracting  from  the  actual  adjusted  costs  for  any  particular  year 
the  amount  of  the  average  cost  for  that  year's  volume  multiplied  by  .00393  times 
the  number  of  years  intervenmg  between  the  year  in  which  the  costs  were  incurred 
and  1938.     This  adjustment  is  shown  in  Table  17. 


14048 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Chart  5 


TOTAL 
AN[ 

1200 

1100 

1000 

1     900 

g     800 

0  600 
-     500 
B     400 

1  300 
200 
100 

0 

COSTS  ADJUSTED  TO  1938  INTEREST,  TAX.  PENSION  AND  WAGE  RATES 
)  1938  PRICE  LEVELS,  BUT  UNADJUSTED  FOR  CHANGED  OPERATING 
CONDITIONS  RELATED  TO  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS 
U.S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

— 

..^' 

1100 
1000 
900     1 

1929 

/ 

^■1929 

1927 

>1937 

1936 

^ 

1930 

^^ 

■935. 

k:. 

600     0 
500     ^ 
400     2 
300     g 
200 
100 
0 

1934 

.< 

^1938 

199 

'>^ 

/ 

^' 

J 

^^ 

0     1      2     3     4      5     6      7     8      9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16    17    18 
MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

Chart 


PER 

z 
0 

i 

Z 

LU 

a. 

CENTAGE  DEVIATIONS  FROM  AVERAGE  -  TOTAL  COSTS   ADJUSTED  T 
INTEREST,  TAX,  PENSION  AND  WAGE  RATES  AND  1938  PRICE  LEVE 
BUT  UNADJUSTED  FOR  CHANGED  OPERATING  CONDITIONS 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

D   1938 
L, 

10 
8 

6 

z 

4       S 

< 

4       0^ 
6 
8 
10 

8 
6 

4 
.2 
0 
2 
4 
6 
8 
10 



— 



— 

— 



"""" 

■ 

glllssiilisi 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14049 


Table    17.- 


-Adjustment   of   Total   Costs  i  for    Time    Trend- 
Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


■United  States  Steel 


A 
Year 

B 

Millions  of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 
Shipped 

C 

Average 
Adjusted 
Costs  for 
Volume  2 

D 

Years 
Prior 
to  1938 

E 

Fractional 
Decrease 
(.00393XD) 

Adjust- 
ment 
(CXE) 

G 

Actual 

Adjusted 

Costs 

H 

Final 

Adjusted 

Costs 

(G-F) 

1927 

13.0 
14.0 
15.1 
11.9 
8.1 
4.4 
6.2 
6.1 
7.6 
11.0 
13.2 
7.8 

932.5 

991,0 

1,055.3 

868.2 
646.1 
429.7 
535.0 
529.1 
616.8 
815.6 
944.2 

13 
10 
9 
8 

7 
6 
5 
4 

2 
1 
0 

. 04323 
. 03930 
. 03537 
.03144 
.02751 
. 02358 
.01965 
.01572 
.01179 
.00786 
.  00393 
.00000 

40.3 
38.9 
37.3 
27.3 
17.8 
10.1 
10.5 
8.3 
7.3 
6.4 
3.7 
0.0 

994.8 
1,005.1 
1,016.3 
866.1 
646.7 
446.  1 
522.5 
518.3 
617.6 
824.6 
919.9 
614.3 

954.5 

1928 

966.2 

1929    . 

979.0 

1930      

838.8 

1931 

628.9 

1932 

436.0 

1933.. 

1934 

512.0 
510.0 

1935 

610.3 

1936 

818.2 

1937 

916.2 

1938 

614.3 

>  Total  costs  adjusted  to  1938  interest,  tax,  pension,  and  wage  rates  and  to  1938  price  levels, 
s  As  indicated  hy  line  of  average  relationship,  Chart  5. 

The  resulting  adjusted  cost  figures  thus  represent  the  original  costs  for  each  of 
the  years  from  1927  to  1938,  adjusted  to  1938  interest,  tax,  pension  and  wage 
rates,  to  1938  price  levels  and  to  1938  general  efficiency.  The  final  adjusted 
figure  for  1938  is,  as  it  should  be,  the  same  as  the  unadjusted  figure  for  that  year, 
except  that  the  social  security  taxes  allocable  to  construction  payroll  have  been 
eliminated.     Table  18  sets  forth  these  costs  in  relation  to  volume.     The  figures 

Table  18. —  Total  Costs  of  Operation  and  Volume  of  Busi7iess — 19S8  Conditions  ' — 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Millions  of  Weighted 

Tons  of  Products 

Shipped 

Costs,  1938 
Conditions 

Year  on  which 

Estimate 

Based 

Millions  of  Weighted 

Tons  of  Products 

Shipped 

Costs,  1938 
Conditions 

Year  on  which 

Estimate 

Based 

436.0 
510.0 
512.0 
610.3 
614.3 
028.9 

1932 
1934 
1933 
1935 
1938 
1931             j 

11.0_ ..-- 

818.2 
83,8.8 
954.5 
916  2 
96(i.  1 
979.0 

1936 

e.i       

11.9. ._ 

1930 

6.2 

13.0 

1927 

76 

13.2 

1937 

78 

140                       

1928 

8  1 

15.1 

1929 

.... 

'  Total  costs  adjusted  to  193S  interest,  pension,  wage  and  tax  rates,  to  1938  price  levels,  and  to  1938 
efficiency. 

are  plotted  on  Chart  7.  A  computation  of  the  line  of  average  relationship  fitted 
to  those  points  by  tiie  least  squares  method  shows  that  the  normal  relation  of  costs 
to  volunie  under  1938  conditions  is  $55.73  per  weighted  ton  shipped,  plus  .$182,- 
100,000,  as  ^vas  stated  in  the  summary.  The  smallness  of  the  deviations  of  the 
actual  costs,  adjusted  to  1938  conditions,  from  the  normal  cost  line  shows  the 
faithfulness  with  which  the  Corporation's  costs  follow  this  pattern. 

IV.  Composition  of  Costs 

If  it  were  not  for  the  fact  that  the  total  costs  obtained  by  adding  together  the 
adjusted  components  of  cost  that  were  developed  in  connection  with  the  deriva- 
tion of  the  total  cost  pattern  had  to  be  adjusted  for  the  gradual  increase  in  effi- 
ciency and  other  changes  in  conditions  over  the  period,  it  would  be  possible  to 
obtain  a  breakdown  of  the  fixed  and  variable  total  costs  simply  by  listing  the  fxed 
and  variable  elements  of  the  various  adjusted  components.  Since  the  total  custs 
were  adjusted  for  these  changes  in  operating  conditions  as  indicated  by  the  long- 
term  trend  in  the  cost-volume  relationship,  an  approximate  breakdown  could 
be  made  only  by  making  a  similar  adjustment  for  time  trend  for  each  of  the  indi- 
vidual compoiMMits  in  which  a  time  trend  exists. 


14050       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Since  the  1938  amounts  of  interest  and  pensions  were  used  for  all  volumes,  no 
time'  trend  adjustment  had  to  be  made  with  regard  to  these  items.  An  inspection 
of  the  movement  of  taxes  and  of  depreciation  and  depletion  with  increases  in 
volume,  as  shown  on  Charts  2  and  3  respectively,  reveals  that  no  appreciable  time 
trend  exists  with  regard  to  these  items.  The  social  security  taxes  will  vary  di- 
rectly with  any  adjustments  that  are  made  in  the  payroll  figure.  It  is  apparent 
that  the  bulk  of  the  adjustment  made  in  the  total  cost  figures  for  time  trend  arose 
from  the  time  trends  involved  in  the  payroll  and  "other  expense"  items.  Clearly, 
then,  it  was  these  two  items  which  had  to  be  adjusted  for  time  trend  in  order  to 
obtain  an  approximate  breakdown  of  total  costs. 

Chart  4  shows  the  payroll  for  each  of  the  various  years  adjusted  to  1938  wage 
rates  and  plotted  against  the  volume  of  goods  shipped  in  the  year  in  which  the 
payroll  was  incurred.  An  inspection  of  this  chart  shows  that,  with  the  exception 
of  1929,  the  payrolls  in  earlier  years,  would  have  been  greater  in  relation  to  volume 
than  the  payrolls  in  1937  and  1938,  if  1938  wage  scales  had  been  in  efifect.  In 
Table  19  the  deviations  of  the  adjusted  payrolls  for  each  of  the  years  from  the 
average  payroll  for  the  volume  involved,  as  indicated  by  the  line  of  average  rela- 
tionship on  Chart  4,  are  computed.  Also  shown  are  the  percentages  by  which 
the  actual  payrolls,  adjusted  to  1938  wage  rates,  are  in  excess  of  or  less  than  the 
average  payroll  for  the  rate  of  operations.  On  Chart  8  these  percentage  devia- 
tions are  plotted  by  years. 

Table  19. — Deviation  of  Payrolls,  Adjusted  to  1938  Wage  Rates,  from  Average  Pay- 
roll for  Volume  Involved — United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Year 

Millions  of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 
Shipped 

Actual  Pay- 
roll Ad- 
justed to 

1938  Rates 

Average 
Adjusted 
Payroll  for 
Volume ' 

Deviation 

Deviation 

as  Per- 
centage of 
Average 

r4.4 

6.1 
0.2 
7.6 
7.8 
8.1 
11.0 
H.9 

193.3 
2G5.6 
243.3 
304.  2 
275.4 
330.  5 
401.5 
483.1 

192.4 
250.3 
253.7 
301.5 
308.3 
318.5 
417.4 
448.0 
485.5 
492  3 
519.6 
657.1 

+0.9 
+15.3 
-10.4 

+2.7 
-32.  9 
+12.0 
-15.9 
+25. 1 
+57.1 
-47.2 

+5.6 
-22.1 

+0.5 

+6.1 

-4.1 

+0.9 

-10.7 

+3.8 

1936 - 

-3.8 

1930                                                      

+7.8 

1927                                                        

1,3.0  i            542.6 

+11.8 

1937                                               

13.2 
14.0 
15.1 

445.1 
525.2 
535.0 

-9.6 

1928                                            

+1.1 

1929                                           

-4.0 

>  As  indicated  by  line  of  average  relationship,  Chart  4. 

It  is  apparent  from  the  chart  that  there  has  been  some  decline  with  the  passage 
of  time  in  the  amount  of  labor  required  to  produce  a  given  quantity  of  steel.  Com- 
putation of  the  least  squares  trend  shows  the  extent  to  which  the  deviations  from 
the  average  are  correlated  with  the  passage  of  time.  As  indicated  on  the  chart, 
payrolls  tended  to  be  7.19%  above  average  in  1927  as  compared  to  7.22%  below 
average  in  1938.  This  represents  a  gradual  increase  in  productivity  per  man- 
hour  during  the  eleven  years  preceding  1938  that  has  resulted  in  a  decrease  in  the 
payroll  recjuired  for  any  given  volume  at  1938  wage  rates  equivalent  to  14.41%  of 
the  averas;e  pavroU  for  that  volume.  This  amounts  to  an  average  decrease  in 
payroll  of  1.31%  of  average  payroll  per  year.  Thus  the  ]iayroll  under  1938  con- 
ditions can  be  estimated  by  subtracting  from  the  actual  payroll  for  any  particular 
year,  adjusted  to  1938  wage  rates,  the  amount  of  the  averace  adjusted  payroll  for 
that  year's  volume,  multiplied  by  .0131  times  the  number  of  years  intervening 
between  the  year  in  which  the  payroll  was  paid  and  1938.  This  adjustment  is 
shown  in  Table  20. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  7 


14051 


RELATIONSHIP  BETWEEN  TOTAL  COSTS  OF  OPERATION 
AND  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS  -  1938  CONDITIONS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

1200 
HOC 
1000 
9^     I 
80)     1 
700     ° 
600     o 
500     ^ 
400    £ 
300     g 
200 
100 
0 

1100 

1000 
-     900 
g     800 
'^     700 
o     600 
^     500 
5     400 

i     300 

200 

100 

^ 

r^ 

■ 

^' 

r 

1927 

<: 

.-928 

^1930 

^ 

1935^ 

^1 

1934. 

,«ni3 

'      ' 

■-. 

^^ 

^X 

/ 

0      1      2     3     4      5     6      7     8      9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16    17    18 
MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

NOTE:  TOT«.  COSTS  AOJUSTtD  TO  1938  INTtREST,  TAX.  FWSION,  UiD  WAGE  RATES;  TO  1938  PRICE  LfVElS.  AND  TO  1938  DMUINCV 

Chart  8 


PERCENTAGE  DEVIATION  FROM  AVERAGE  - 

PAYROLLS  ADJUSTED  TO  1938  WAGE  RATES 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 


1 

— 

— 

- 

V"-" 

^-J 



^_^ 

^- 



1 
1 

i 

1 

^    \ 

I  \ 

\ 

3 

R      ; 

\ 

\      \ 

%      \ 

\      \ 

\                 \ 

14052    "   CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Table  20. — Adjustment  of  Payrolls,  Adjusted  to  1938  Wage  Rates,  for  Time  Trend — 
Uniterir States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


(B) 

Millions  of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 
Shipped 


Average 
Adjusted 
Payroll  for 
Volume ' 


(D) 


(E) 


Fractional 
Decrease 


(F) 


Adjust- 
ment 

(CXE) 


Actual 
Adjusted 
Payrolls 


(H) 

Final 
Adjusted 
Payroll 
(O-F) 


1927 
1928 
1929 
1930 
1931 
1932 
1933 
1934 
1935 
1936 
1937 


13.0 
14.0 
15.1 
11.9 
8.1 
4.4 
6.2 
G.  1 
7.6 
11.0 
13.2 
7.8 


485.5 
519.6 
557.1 
448.0 
318.5 
192.4 
253.7 
250.3 
301.5 
417.4 
492.3 
308.3 


.117882 
. 104784 
.091686 
. 0785S8 
.  065490 
.  052,'<92 
.  039294 
.026196 
.013098 
.000000 


65.7 
46.9 
29.2 
15.1 
16.6 
13.1 


542.6 
525.2 
535.0 
483.1 
330.5 
193.3 
24.3.3 
265.6 
304.  2 
401.5 
445.1 
275.4 


472.7 
457.1 
469.3 
436.2 
301.3 
178.2 
226.7 
252.5 
292.4 
390.6 
438.7 
275.4 


'  As  indicated  by  line  of  average  relationship,  Chart  4. 

Table  21. — Payrolls,  Adjusted  to  1938  Wage  Rates  and  Efficiency,  Related  to  Vol- 
ume of  Business — •  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Millions  of  Weighted  Tons 
of  Products  Shipped 

Payroll- 
1938  Con- 
ditions 

Year  on 
which 

Estimate 
Based 

Millions  of  Weighted  Tons 
of  Products  Shipped 

Payroll- 
1938  Con- 
ditions 

Year  on 
which 

Estimate 
Based 

178.2 
252.5 
226.7 
292.4 
275.4 
301.3 

1932 
1934 
1933 
193f 

im 

1931 

390.6 
436.2 
472.7 
438.7 
457.1 
460.3 

6.1 

6.2 

13.0          

7.fi 

13.2 

14.0 

7.8 

8.1 

15.1 

1929 

In  Table  21  are  shown  the  payrolls,  at  1938  wage  rates  and  at  1938  efficiency 
as  indicated  by  the  time  trend  adjust;iients,  for  each  of  the  various  tonnages 
shipped  during  the  1927-1938  period.  On  Chart  9  these  final  adjusted  payroll 
figures  are  plotted  in  relation  to  volume.  A  straight  line,  fitted  to  the  points  by 
the  least  squares  method,  indicates  that  the  total  payroll  under  1938  conditions 
will  amount  to  $02,100,000  plus  $29.10  per  weighted  ton  of  product  shipped. 

Table  22. — Deviation  of  Adjusted  ^  "Other  Expenses"  From  Average  for  Volume 
Involved — United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Year 

Millious  of 

Weighted  Tons 

of  Products 

Shipped 

Actual  "Other 

Expenses" 

Adjusted  for 

Price 

Average  "Other 
Expenses" 
for  Volume 
Involved  ' 

Deviation 

De\:iation  a.<! 

Percentage  of 

Average 

1932 

4.4 
6.1 
6.2 
7.6 
7.8 
K.  1 
11.0 
11.9 
13.0 
13.2 
14.0 
15.1 

156.  8 
148.9 
176.6 
202.7 
228.  7 
203.  7 
297.5 
247.7 
312.7 
336.3 
331.  4 
334.8 

143. 1 
175.8 
177.7 
204.6 
208  4 
214.2 
269.  9 
287.2 
308.3 
312.2 
327.6 
348.7 

+  1,3.7 
-26.9 

-1. 1 

-1.9 
4  20.3 
-10.5 
+27.6 
-39.5 

H-4.4 
+24.1 

+3.8 
-13.9 

+9.6 

1933     

-0.6 

1935 

-0.9 

1938 

+9.7 

1931 

-4  9 

1936 

+  10.2 

1930 

— 13.  8 

1927 . 

+  14 

+7.7 

1928 

+1.2 

1929 

-4.0 

'  "Other  Expenses"  adjusted  for  changes  in  the  general  price  level  as  indicated  by  the  B.  T,.  S.  index  of 
wholesale  prices  for  commodities  other  than  food  and  farm  product*:  assuming  50%  of  items  affected. 
'  As  indicated  by  line  of  a\  onige  relationship,  Chart  10. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POAVER 


14053 


Chart 


PAYROLLS,  ADJUSTED  TO  1938  CONDITIONS, 
RELATED  TO  VOLUME  OF  BUSiUESS 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 


600 

.^' 

f    400 

o 

<o    300 

z 
o 

=!     200 

s 

100 

0 

1930, 

:k'«h 

,'' 

im 

1934 

•l933 

1938 

1931 

/- 

^^ 

1932 

0      1      2      3      4      5      6      7     8      9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16    17 
MILUONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 


NOTI:   PAYDOIU  ARE  AOJUSTtO  TO  1938  WACC  RATES  AND  EfnCJENCr 


600 

tf> 
cc 

500     < 

_i 
o 

400  ° 
u. 
O 

300     in 

z 
o 

20b  d 

s 
100 


Chart  10 


700 
600 

"OTHER  tXPLNSES",  ADJUSTED  TO  1938  PRICE  LEVEL, 
RELATED  TO  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

600 
500     < 

s 

300     to 

o 

200     ^ 

s 

100 
0 

<     500 

!  «o 

o 

V)     300 

z 
o 

d     200 

100 

0 

IPJ7, 

i^. 

1928 

'1929 

''' 

1938^ 

•  1931 

"' 

-- 

1930* 

^. 

i9. 

1934 

59M 

19*35 

"' 

^' 

( 

NOTE;  AOJUSTVE 
BY  THE  B 

)      1      2      3     4      5     6      7     8      9     10    11    12    13    14    15    15    17    1 
MILLIONS  OC  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRnnilCTS  SHIPPED 

NT  TO  1938  PRICE  LEVEL  MADE  ON  ASSUMPTION  THAT  ONLY  HAl/  OF  ITEMS  FLUCTUATE  WITH  THE  GENERAL  PRICE  l£»a 
LS.  INDEX  OF  WHOLESALE  PRICES  FOR  COMMODITIES  OTHER  THAN  FOOD  AND  FARM  PRODUCTS 

8 

14054 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


A  similar  time  trend  computation  and  adjustment  has  been  made  with  regard 
to  the  item  "other  expenses."  Chart  10  shows  the  "other  expense"  items  adjusted 
for  changes  in  the  general  price  level,  as  per  Table  14.  The  computation  of  the 
average  relationship  shows  that  these  cost  items  tend  to  amount  to  $58,600,000 
plus  $19.21  per  weighted  ton  of  product  shipped.  The  deviations  from  this  line 
are  in  some  instances  fairly  large  and  in  general  it  would  appear  that  "other 
expenses"  tended  to  be  below  average  in  the  earlier  years  and  above  average 
toward  the  end  of  the  1927-1938  period.  In  Table  22  are  shown  the  deviations 
and  the  percentage  deviations  from  average  of  the  "other  expense"  items  adjusted 
for  price  changes.  Chart  11  shows  the  percentage  deviations,  plotted  by  years. 
Computation  of  the  general  trend  shows  that  they  are  correlated  with  the  pas.sage 
of  time  in  such  a  way  that  "other  expenses"  at  1938  price  levels  tend  to  be  5.21  % 
below  average  in  1927,  as  against  5.26%  above  average  in  1938,  representing  an 
increase  over  the  eleven  year  period  prior  to  1938  amounting  to  10.47%  of  average, 
or  .95%  of  average  per  year.  The  adjustment  of  the  figures  for  each  of  the 
respective  j'ears  for  this  time  trend  is  made  in  Table  23.  In  Table  24  the  final 
adjusted  figures  are  shown  in  connection  with  the  volume  of  shipments  involved. 
In  Chart  12  the  "other  expense"  items,  adjusted  for  both  price  changes  and  time 
trend,  are  shown  in  relation  to  volume.  Computation  of  the  line  of  average 
relationship  shows  that  undei  1938  conditions  "other  expenses"  tend  to  amount 
to  $21.40  per  weighted  ton  plus  $50,900,000. 


Table  23. 


-Adjustment  of  Adjusted  "Other  Expenses"  for  Time  Trend — United 
States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


(A) 
Year 

(B) 

Millions  of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 
Shipped 

(C) 

Average 
Adjusted 
"Other  Es- 
penses"  • 

(D) 

Years  Prior 
to  1938 

(E) 

Fractional 

Increase 

(.009521 X 

D) 

(F) 

Adjust- 
ment 
(CXE) 

(O) 

Actual 
Adjusted 
"Other  Ex- 
penses" 

(H) 

Final 
Adjusted 
"Other  Ex- 
penses" 
(Q+F) 

1927_. 

1928 

13.0 
14.0 
15.1 
11.9 
8.1 
4.4 
6.2 
6.1 
7.6 
11.0 
13.2 
7.8 

308.3 
327.6 
348.7 
287.2 
214.2 
143.1 
177.7 
175.8 
204.6 

312^2 
208.4 

11 
10 

9 
8 
7 
6 
5 
4 
3 
2 
1 
0 

.  104731 
.095210 
.  085689 
.  076168 
.066647 
.  057128 
.  047605 
.  038084 
.  028563 
.  019042 
.  009521 
.000000 

32.3 
31.2 
29.9 

14!3 
8.2 
8.5 
6.7 
5.8 
5.1 
3.0 
0.0 

312.7 
331.4 
334.8 
247.7 
203.7 
156.8 
176.6 
148.9 
202.7 
297.5 
336.3 
228.7 

345.0 
362  6 

1929 

364.7 

1930 

1931 

218.0 

1932-     ... 

165.0 

1933 

185.1 

1934_. 

155.6 

1935,. 

208.5 

1936    . 

1937.... 

339.3 

1938 

228.7 

'  For  volume  involved,  as  indicated  by  line  of  average  relationship,  Chart  10. 

Table  24. — "Other  Expenses",  Adjusted  to  19S3  Price  Levels  and  Operating  Con- 
ditions, Related  to  Volume  of  Business — United  States  Steel  Corporation  and 
Subsidiaries 


Millions  of  Weighted  Tons 
of  Products  Shipped 

Other  Ex- 
penses— 
1938  Con- 
ditions 

Year  on 
which  Esti- 
mate Based 

Millions  of  Weighted  Tons 
of  Products  Shipped 

Other  Ex- 

ir3r^^on- 
ditions 

which  Esti- 
mate Based 

4.4 

165.0 
155.6 
185.1 
208.5 
228.7 
218.0 

iiiiii 

11.0 

302.6 
269.0 
345.0 

364!  7 

1936 

6.1,..-    . 

11.9 

1930 

6.2... 

13.0 

1927 

7.6 

13.2 

1937 

7.8 

14.0 

1928 

8.1 

15.1 

1929 

CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  11 


14055 


PERCENTAGE  DEVIATION  FROM  AVERAGE  - 

OTHER  EXPENSES  ADJUSTED  FOR  PRICE  CHANGES 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 


20 

15 

z 

o 

10 

rfi 

5 

o 

UJ 

0 

^ 

5 

10 

15 

20 

25 

Chart  12 


"OTH 
FOR  ( 

500 

CO     400 

< 

§     300 
o 

z     200 
o 

^     100 
0 

ER  EXPENSES",  ADJUSTED  FOR  CHANGES  IN  COMMODITY  PRICES  AND 
CHANGED  OPERATING  CONDITIONS,  RELATED  TO  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

^^- 

400     ^ 

<: 

300     2 

o 

200     z 
o 

100     ^ 

1936 

19. 

19:3 

''' 

r,','^' 

193«, 

iT931 

.^' 

• 

.930 

_ 

"!- 

ISM 

,''' 

"1 

( 

NOTE:    BASIS  Of 
OF  DCVWt 

)      1      2      3     4      5      6      7      8     9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16    17    1 
MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

ADJUSTMtNTS-  (11  B  LS.  INOU  Of  WHOLESALE  PRICES  fOR  COMMODITIES  OTHER  THAN  FOOO  AND  f»RM  PROCuaS  AND 
ONS  FROM  AVERAGE 

8 

(2)  TIME  IRtNB 

14056       OONOENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Adding  together  the  fixed  and  variable  elements  of  the  final  adjusted  com- 
ponents of  cost  gives  the  following  result: 

Table  25. — Elements  of  Total  Costs  Adjusted  to  1938  Conditions* — United  States 
Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Itpm 

FLxed 

Variable 

Interest                                                                     -            -  .          ... 

$8,300,000 
7.  700, 000 
24,200,000 
29,500,000 
62,100,000 
2,500,000 
50,900,000 

$0. 00  per  ton 

Pensions                                                                 -      

0.00  "     " 

Taxes                                                            -  .  -    

1.43   "     " 

2.37   "     '• 

29.10  "     " 

1.16   "     " 

21.40    "     " 

$185,  200, 000 

•  Elements  of  cost  individually  adjustee^  to  1938  interest,  tax,  pension,  and  wage  rates;  to  1938  price  levels; 
and  for  time  trend. 


The  total  fixed  and  variable  costs  obtained  by  this  calculation  are  thus  seen  to 
be  substantially  the  same  as  the  results  obtained  by  adjusting  total  costs,  instead 
.of  the  individual  components,  for  time  trend.  It  would  seem  that  the  time  trend 
adjustment  made  with  respect  to  total  costs  would  represent  the  more  accurate 
figure  of  the  two.  First  of  all,  it  includes  any  slight  time  trends  that  may  exist 
with  regard  to  the  other  components.  Secondly,  as  has  already  been  mentioned 
in  connection  with  the  discussion  of  the  derivation  of  the  total  cost  curve,  the 
payroll  figures  are  not  comparable  with  shipments  to  the  extent  that  production  is 
greater  or  less  than  shipments.  Consequently  some  of  the  deviations  on  which 
the  payroll  time  trend  was  estimated  may  be  the  result  of  inventory  fluctuations. 
Similarly,  since  the  "other  expense'"  classification  was  simply  the  residual  amount 
after  deducting  from  total  costs  the  other  components  of  cost,  the  amount  of 
this  item  for  each  year  has  been  overstated  to  the  same  extent  that  payroll  has 
been  understated,  or  vice  versa,  because  of  inventory  fluctuations,  and  some  of  the 
deviations  on  which  the  "other  expense"  time  trend  was  computed  may  also  hare 
been  the  result  of  the  inventory  situation.  Since  total  costs  were  extracted  from 
the  profit  and  loss  statements  and  represent  the  sum  of  any  offsetting  errors  in 
"other  expenses"  and  payroll,  they  are  comparable  with  shipments  and  the 
deviations  cannot  be  attributed  to  inventory  fluctuations,  except  to  the  minute 
extent  that  the  situation  just  described  resulted  in  payroll  adjustments  being 
applied  to  a  small  portion  of  costs  which  should  have  been  classified  as  "other 
expense,"  and  vice  versa. 

Assuming,  then,  that  the  total  costs  of  $182,100,000  plus  $55.73  per  weighted 
ton  of  product  shipped,  developed  by  adjusting  total  costs  for  time  trend,  repre- 
sents the  more  accurate  figure,  the  approximation  of  the  components  of  total 
costs  under  1938  conditions  may  be  revised  as  follows: 


Table  26. 


■Elements   of    Total    Costs — Revised    1938    Conditions- 
Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


■United   Slates 


Interest .-- ..- 

Pensions. _-- - .-. 

Taxes  other  than  Social  Security  and  Federal  Income 

Depreciation  and  Depletion 

Payroll 

Social  Security  Taxes 

Other  Expenses 

Total  Costs 


$8,  3fKl,  000 

$0. 00  per  ton 

7,  7m>,  000 

0.00   •'     " 

24,200,000 

1.43    "      " 

29.  5(»0,  000 

2.37   "     " 

62,  100,  n(X) 

29.10    "      " 

2,  .W  000 

1.  16    "      " 

47,  800,  000 

21.67    "     " 

$182, 100,  00' 

$,-5. 73  per  ton 

The  entire  adjustment  has  been  nadc  in  tli  "other  expense"  figures  because 
the  adjustment  does  not  involve  a  relativoh-  large  amount  in  any  event,  and 
because  the  "other  expense"  r'a.^sification  n^prescnts  a  conglomeration  of  items 
and  is  the  least  accurate  claspiMv^tion  anyiow.  Chart  13  graphically  portrays 
the  relation  of  the  various  eleuicnt?  of  co.'^t  to  volume.  The  differences  between 
the  two  estimates  of  fixed  and  variaMlo  cosi-^^  shown  above  are  so  small  that  the 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  13 


14057 


COMPOSITION  OF  TOTAL  COSTS  OF  OPERATION 
IN  RELATION  TO  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

7 


1200 


6     7     8     9    10  11    1?   13  14   lb  16  17  18  "mtWEST 

killIONs  of  weighted  tons  of  all 
tonnage  products  shipped 


NOTE:    19271938  CXPtRltNCE  AOJUSTtD  TO  1938  CONDITIONS 


graphing  of  either  upon  the  chart  would  show  the  same  result.  The  "other  ex- 
pense" item  has  been  labeled  "goods  and  services  purchased,  etc."  on  the  chart 
to  indicate  its  general  nature. 

Segregating  the  cash  from  the  non-cash  items,  the  cost.pattern  of  the  Corpora- 
tion under  1938  conditions  is  as  follows: 


Table    27. — Cash   and 


Non-Cash    Costs    1938    Conditions- 
Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


■  United    States    Steel 


Item 

Fixed 

Variable 

$8,  300,  000 
7,  700,  000 

24,200,000 

62, 100,  000 
2,  500,  000 

47,  800, 000 

0.00     "    ■' 

1.43    "    " 

Payroll 

29.10     "    " 

1.16     "     " 

21.67     "    " 

Total  Cash  Costs 

152,000,000 
29,  500,  000 

53  36  per  ton 

Depreciation  and  Depletion 

2  37     "    " 

Total  Costs 

$182, 100,  000 

$55.  73  per  ton 

14058       COXOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  question  frequently  arises  as  to  what  portion  of  the  total  costs  of  the  United 
States  Steel  Corporation  represents  fixed  costs  and  what  portion  represents 
variable  costs.  These  percentages  will  differ,  of  course,  with  the  volume  of 
shipments,  because  by  definition,  fixed  costs  remain  the  same  regardless  of  the 
quantity  produced,  while  variable  costs  increase  with  each  additional  ton  of 
product.  The  percentages  of  fixed  to  total  costs  at  various  operating  rates  are 
shown  in  Table  28.  The  computation  and  significance  of  the  "Average  Equiv- 
lent  Percentage  of  Unweighted  Rolled  and  Finished  Capacity"  shown  in  the 
table  are  explained  in  Section  VI,  "Weighted  Tonnages  and  the  Operating  Rate." 

Table  28. — Percentage  of  Fixed  to  Total  Costs  at  Various  Rates  of  Operation — 1938 
Conditions — United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 

[Total  costs  =  $,'i5.734  per  weighted  ton  of  product  shipped  +  $182,100,000.    Fixed  costs  =  $182,100,0001 


Millions  of  VV'eighted  Tons  of  Products 
Shipped 

Average 
Equivalent 
Percentage  of 
,Unweighted 
Rolled  and  Fin- 
ished Capacity 
(See  Table  37) 

Fixed  Costs 

(Millions  of 

Dollars) 

Total  Costs 

(Millions  of 

Dollars) 

Percentage 
Fixed  to  Total 

2.45... 

10 
20 
30 
40 
50 
60 
70 
80 
90 
100 

182.1 

182: 1 

182.1 

182.1 

182.1 

182. 1  . 

182.1 

182.1 

182.1 

318.6 
414.5 
509.3 
605.1 
700.4 
795.  2 
891.0 
986.3 
1031.6 
1177.0 

57.2 

4.17 

43.9 

6.87 

35.8 

7.59 — --. 

30.1 

9.30 

26.0 

11.00 

22.9 

12.72 

20.4 

14.43 -.... 

18.5 

16.14 

16.8 

17.85 

15.4 

V.  Relation  c     Costs  and  Volume  to  Prices 

Knowing  the  relation  between  volume  and  total  cost,  it  becomes  important  to 
determine  the  way  in  which  decreased  prices  fit  into  the  picture.  To  determine 
whether  price  reductions  would  pay  or  would  involve  prohibitive  losses,  it  is 
necessary  to  compare  the  increase  in  volume  and  the  total  revenues  which  might 
be  anticipated  if  prices  were  reduced  with  the  total  costs  of  producing  the  tonnage 
involved.  The  Corporation's  shipments  could  be  increased  through  price. reduc- 
tion, if  at  all,  only  by  increasing  the  total  amount  of  steel  consumed,  since  com- 
petitive meeting  of  prices  by  other  producers  would  prevent  increased  participa- 
tion in  the  going  volume  of  business.  It  is  important  to  bear  in  mind  that  the 
rise  to  be  expected  in  the  total  volume  of  steel  consumed  as  a  result  of  a  drop  in 
prices  is  not  very  great  in  the  steel  industry.  Steel  is  not  sold  directly  to  the 
ultimate  consumer.  It  reaches  him  only  as  a  part  of  the  finished  automobile, 
refrigerator,  typewriter,  apartment  house,  tin  can,  or  safety  pin,  as  the  case  may 
be.  In  other  cases,  steel  is  used  only  as  part  of  the  machinery  and  equipment 
used  in  making  the  products  which  reach  the  man  in  the  street.  No  matter  how 
low  the  price,  steel  can  be  sold  only  if  products  which  are  produced  from  steel  or 
by  the  use  of  steel  are  being  sold.  In  the  case  of  products  produced  from  steel, 
the  cost  of  the  steel  is  usually  so  small  a  fraction  of  the  total  cost  of  the  product 
that  a  reduction  in  steel  prices,  even  if  passed  on  to  the  ultimate  consumer,  would 
not  result  in  a  sufficient  decrease  in  the  price  of  the  finished  product  to  cause  an 
appreciable  increase  in  its  sale.  As  far  ag  steel  for  production  equipment  is  con- 
cerned, it  goes  without  saying  that  regardless  of  the  price  of  steel  no  one  will 
invest  in  productive  machinery  unless  he  feels  the  prospects  in  this  particular 
line  of  business  justify  such  investment. 

Analysis  of  the  iniluence  of  price  as  a  factor  affecting  steel  consumption  in  the 
automobile,  railroad  and  container  industries  reveals  that  a  decrease  in  the  price 
of  steel  can  increase  the  consumption  of  steel  only  t.  >  a  limited  extent  by  promoting 
the  use  of  more  steel  per  unit  or  permitting  steel  to  be  substituted  for  some  other 
competing  material.  Any  substantial  increase  in  the  consumption  of  steel  in 
these  industries  could  be  brought  about  only  by  increasing  the  consumption  of 
the  finished  product  or  service  rendered.  Consequently,  the  price  elasticity  of 
the  demand  for  steel  depends  primarily  upon  the  price  elasticity  of  demand  for 
the  finished  product  and  the  relative  cost  of  steel  to  the  price  of  the  finished  product. 
The  elasticity  of  demand  is  measured  by  the  ratio  of  the  relative  resulting  increase 


GONOPNTRATJON  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14059 

in  volume  to  the  relative  decrease  in  price.  For  example,  in  the  case  of  automo- 
biles, an  exhaustive  study  by  Messrs.  Roos  and  von  Szeliski  *  found  that  the  price 
elasticity  of  demand  for  automobiles  was  about  1.5,  which  means  that  a  1% 
reduction  in  price  would  increase  the  number  of  automobiles  sold  about  1.5%. 
Since  the  cost  of  steel  in  the  -form  sold  by  the  steel  producers  is  about  one-tenth 
of  the  retail  price  of  a  representative  low-priced  automobile,  it  follows  that  a 
reduction  of  10%  in  the  price  of  steel,  even  if  the  saving  in  cost  is  passed  on  to 
the  ultimate  consumer,  can  efiFect  at  most  only  a  1  %  reduction  in  the  price  of  the 
delivered  automobile.  A  price  reduction  of  that  amount,  as  has  been  stated, 
could  bring  about  but  a  1.5%  increase  in  the  number  of  automobiles  sold  and  in 
the  amount  of  steel  used  in  the  automobile  industry.  The  increased  consumption 
arising  out  of  the  extent  to  which  steel  might  be  substituted  for  some  other  ma- 
terial, or  the  extent  to  which  the  use  of  steel  per  automobile  might  be  increased 
if  steel  prices  were  reduced,  would  probably  not  increase  the  elasticity  by  more 
than  .1.  Taking  into  account  all  factors  and  making  a  liberal  allowance  for 
possible  error,  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  automotive  steel  is  not  in  excess 
of  .2  or  .3. 

The  price  elasticities  for  the  finished  products  or  services  in  the  container  and 
railroad  industries  have  not  had  the  benefit  of  as  definite  measurement  as  that 
made  of  the  demand  for  automobiles  by  Messrs.  Roos  and  von  Szeliski,  but  the 
evidence  indicates  that  the  demand  for  these  products  is  considerably  less  elastic 
than  the  demand  for  automobiles.  Moreover,  analyses  of  all  the  factors  influencing 
steel  consumption  in  these  industries,  even  assuming  an  elasticity  of  demand  for 
the  finished  products  and  services  as  high  as  2,  show  definitely  that  the  price 
elasticity  of  the  demand  for  steel  in  each  of  the  respective  industries  is  considerably 
less  than  1.  A  mathematical  analysis  of  the  correlation  between  the  amount  of 
all  steel  sold  and  the  various  factors,  including  price,  which  influence  the  quantity 
sold,  reveals  that  a  negligible  portion  of  the  fluctuations  in  the  quantity  sold  ^re 
attributable  to  price  and  that  a  steel  price  change,  other  factors  remaining  un- 
changed, will  not  result  in  as  great  a  percentage  change  in  the  volume  of  steel 
sold.  This  confirms  the  individual  analyses  of  the  principal  steel  consuming 
industries  already  mentioned. 

While  the  above  analyses  indicate  clearly  that  the  elasticity  of  the  demand  for 
steel  is  considerably  less  than  1,  it  has  been  assumed  for  the  purposes  of  this 
study,  in  order  to  use  a  figure  that  is  beyond  question,  that  the  elasticity  of 
demand  for  steel  is  as  high  as  1.  An  elasticity  of  1  means  that  any  decrease  "in 
price  will  result  in  a  proportional  increase  in  volume  which  will  keep  the  total 
sales  in  dollars  unchanged.  This  is  to  say  that  for  small  changes  in  price  a  given 
percentage  decrease,  such  as  a  5%  reduction  in  price,  will  result  approximately  in 
the  same  percentage  increase  in  volume  sold.^ 

It  is  evident  that  unless  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  the  product  exceeds  1  by 
a  substantial  margin,  the  theory  that  price  reduction  in  and  by  itself  would 
produce  profits  through  increased  volume  is  utterly  fallacious,  not  only  for  the 
United  States  Steel  Corporation,  but  for  any  business  or  any  industry.  Since, 
with  the  elasticity  of  demand  equalling  1,  the  total  sales  receipts  would  remain 
the  same,  for  the  theory  to  work  the  total  costs  of  producing  the  greater  volume 
would  also  have  to  be  the  same  or  less.  For  example,  no  increased  payroll  could 
be  incurred  to  produce  the  greater  volume.  Such  a  condition  could  exist  only 
when  all  costs  were  "fixed"  or  "overhead"  and  none  were  "additional"  or  "vari- 
able." Only  then  would  the  cost  per  unit  go  down,  relatively,  as  fast  as  the 
volume  went  up.  Application  of  the  theory  of  increased  profits  through  price 
reduction  could  thus  only  produce  loss  to  the  enterprise  which  adopted  it.  The 
actual  amount  to  be  lost  "by  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  through  reducing 
prices,  however,  and  the  amount  by  which  the  increase  in  volume  to  be  e.^cpected 
as  a  result  of  reducing  steel  prices  falls  short  of  the  increase  needed  to  offset  the 
price  reduction,  can  be  estimated  only  by  including  in  the  computation  the  rela- 
tionship which  exists  between  costs  and  volume. 

The  sales  of  the  subsidiaries  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  to  outside 
customers,  less  discounts,  returns  and  allowances,  amounted  in  1938  to  $560,508,- 
302.96.  This  amount  is  net,  after  deduction  of  freight  paid  on  shipments  to  cus- 
tomers,. The  transportation  and  miscellaneous  revenues,  after  excluding  the 
estimated  amount  of  inter-company  profits,  amounted  to  approximately  $45,267,- 
000.     The  weighted  tonnage  of  all  products  shipped  amounted  to  approximately 

*  C.  F.  Roos  and  Victor  von  Szeliski,  "Factors  Governing  Changes  in  Domestic  Automobile  Demand," 
The  Dynamics  of  Automobile  Demand.  General  Motors  Corporation,  N.  Y.,  1939. 

»  For  computation  of  percentage  increases  in  volume  which  would  result  from  various  percentage  decreases 
in  price  if  elasticity  of  demand  were  1,  see  Appendix  II. 

124491— 41— pt.  26 31 


14060 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEll 


7,800,000  weighted  tons.     The  sales  and  revenues  per  weighted  ton  for  1938, 
therefore,  are  made  up  as  follows: 

Table  29. — Sales  and  Other  Operating  Revenues  1988 — United  States  Steel  Corpora- 
tion and  Subsidiaries 


Item 

Total 
(MUlions) 

Per  Weighted 
Tons  of  Prod- 
ucts Shipped 

Sales 

$560,508 
45.267 

5.80 

Total  sales  and  revenues 

$605.  775 

$77  66 

Sales  and  revenues  for  1938  thus  averaged  $77.66  per  weighted  ton  of  tonnage 
products  shipped. 

It  should  be  borne  in  mind,  however,  that  any  profit  or  loss  estimates  based 
on  these  figures  suppose  1938  average  sales  per  weighted  ton.  To  the  extent  that 
prices  are  not  always  proportional  to  costs,  to  the  extent  that  some  products  sell 
for  a  higher  or  lower -■■price  than  others  costing  the  same  to  produce,  the  1938 
average  sales  per  weighted  ton  is  afifected  by  the  quantities  of  each  particular 
product  sold,  as  well  as  by  the  prices  prevailing.  Hence  the  profit  or  loss  esti- 
mates contained  in  the  summary  are  accurate  for  1938  average  sales  per  weighted 
ton,  but  different  products  might  be  sold  in  another  year  which  would  constitute 
the  same  weighted  tonnage  when  weighted  on  a  cost  basis,  but  which  would  carry 
diflFerent  profit  margins  and  thus  result  in  a  slightly  diff'erent  average  sales  per 
weighted  ton  figure,  although  the  actual  1938  prices  for  each  product  had  not 
changed.  The  possibihty  that  an  over-all  price  reduction  in  1938  would  have 
materially  changed  the  proportion  of  sales  constituted  by  each  type  of  product 
would,  however,  seem  rather  remote. 

Furthermore,  in  computing  the  total  sales  and  revenue  at  various  shipment 
levels,  it  has  been  assumed  that  the  revenues  from  transportation  and  miscella- 
neous operations  rise  and  fall  approximately  as  product  shipments  go  up  and 
down.  That  this  has  been  the  general  relation  of  transportation  and  miscellane- 
ous revenues  to  the  volume  of  steel  and  other  manufacturing  business  done  may 
be  seen  from  Chart  14.  The  data  on  vhich  this  chart  is  based  are  given  in  Table 
30.  The  transportation  and  miscellaneous  revenues,  after  deducting  estimated 
inter-company  items,  amounted  in  1938  to  $5.80  per  weighted  ton  and  it  is  assumed 
for  the  purposes  of  this  study  that  they  would  increase  sufficiently  so  as  stiU  to 
amount  to  $5.80  per  ton  if  the  volume  of  products  sold  were  increased.  It  should 
be  noted,  however,  that  the  1938  transportation  and  miscellaneous  revenues  were 
higher  than  average  in  relation  to  the  volume  of  products  shipped  and  that  in 
recent  years  there  has  been  a  tendency  for  these  revenues  to  fall  off  somewhat 
per  ton  of  product  shipped  when  the  higher  levels  of  production  are  reached,  as 
is  indicated  by  the  position  of  the  points  for  1930,  1936  and  1937.  Hence  it  is 
rather  likely  that  at  the  higher  operating  rates  the  total  sales  and  revenues 
wotild  be  silghtly  less  than  estimated  in  this  study.  To  the  extent  that  trans- 
portation and  miscellaneous  operating  revenues  might  fail  to  increase  proportion- 
ately with  increases  in  shipments,  the  losses  entaUed  through  pride  reduction 
woiUd  be  greater  than  those  described. 


OONOENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  14 


14061 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  MISCELLANEOUS  REVENUES  RELATED  TO  SHIPMENTS 
U.  S.  STCEL  CORPORAHON  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

90 
</>     80 

f: 

S      50 

i   ^ 

5     30 
^     20 

10 
0 

>1929 

y 

90 

80     w 
70     5 
60     % 
50     ^ 
40     1 
30     - 
20     ^ 
10 
0 

U27 

:? 

y 

y 

y 

y 

/ 

1936 

1930 

•l937 

1938, 
193S 

y 

1934 

y 

^ 

1931 

1S32 

y 

w 

y 

/ 

^ 

0     1     2     3     4     5     6     7     8     9    10    11    12    13    14   15    16    17    18 
MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

HOTt:  m.  IMTER-eOWWY  fIDIS  EXCtUOED 

Table  30.- 


■Trans'poTtation  and  Miscellaneous  Revenues  '  Related  to  Shipments — 
United  States  Steel  CorporaticM  and  Subsidiaries 


Millions  of  Weighted  Tons  of  Products  Shipped 

Year 

Net  Sales  and 

Revenues 

(Millions  of 

Dollars) 

Net  Sales 

(Millions  of 

Dollars) 

Transporta- 
tion and  Mis- 
cellaneous 
(MUlions  of 
DoUars) 

4.4 

1932 
1934 
1933 
1935 
1938 
1931 
1936 
1930 
1927 
1937 
1928 
1929 

283.5 
418.5 
371.0 
539.9 
605.8 
523.7 
791.7 
814.4 
946.6 

1021. 6 
992.6 

1067. 8 

261.7 
388.5 
345.3 
500.8 
560.5 
488.7 
738.5 
760.8 
861.4 
C64.4 
903.9 
972.3 

21.8 

6.1 

6.2 

30.0 
25.7 

7.6 

39.1 

53.2 

63.6 

85.2 

13.2     

57.2 

88.7 

15.1 

95.5 

'  Estimated  amount  of  inter-company  items  excluded. 


14062 


CONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


On  the  other  hand,  the  greatest  extent  to  which  it  is  likely  that  fluctuations  in 
the  revenues  from  transportation  and  miscellaneous  operations  per  ton  of  products 
sold  will  change  the  picture  presented  may  be  seen  from  the  fact  that  the  trans- 
portation and  miscellaneous  revenues  have  averaged  only  7.5%  of  total  sales  and 
revenues  over,  the  period  1927-1938  and  that  the  transportation  and  miscel- 
laneous revenues  per  ton  of  product  sold  have  never  in  that  period  amounted  to 
more  than  75  cents  above  or  $1.65  below  the  1938  figure.  The  figures  for 
each  year,  together  with  the  deviations  from  the  1938  figure,  are  given  in  Table  31. 
The  effect  of  such  possible  deviations  on  the  profit  computations  that  have  been 
based  on  these  sales  and  revenue  figures  is  further  minimized  by  the  fact  that  the 
cost  of  these  operations  would  also  be  likely  to  fall  at  least  partly  as  much  as  the 
revenues  derived  therefrom. 

Taking  $77.66,  then  as  the  total  sales  and  revenue  per  weighted  ton  at  average 
1938  price  levels,  the  practical  effect  of  the  comparative  inelasticity  of  demand 
for  steel  may  be  examined. 

Table  31. — Transportation  and  Miscellaneous  Revenues   Per   Weighted    Ton   of 
Products  Shipped — United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Year 

Millions  of 
Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 
Shipped 

Transporta- 
tion and 
Miscellaneous 
Revenues 

(  Millions  of 
Dollars) 

Per 

Weighted 
Ton 

Deviation 
from  1938 

1027 

13.0 
14.0 
15.1 
11.9 
8.1 
4.4 
6.2 
6.1 
7.6 
11.0 
13.2 
7.8 

85.2 
88.7 
95.5 
53.6 
35.0 
21.8 
25.7 
30.0 
39.1 
53.2 
57.2 
45.3 

$6.55 
6.34 
6.32 
4.50 
4.32 
4.95 
4.15 
4.92 
6.14 
4.84 
4.33 
6.80 

1928 

1929. 

+0.62 

1930 

-1.30 

1931. 

-L48 

1932 

—  0  86 

1933 

-1.65 

1934 

-0.88 

1935 

-0.66 

1936 

—0  96 

1937 

—  1  47 

1938 

—0.00 

In  1937  approximately  13,200,000  weighted  tons  of  products  were  shipped  by 
the  Corporation's  subsidiaries.  In  1938  this  tonnage  dropped  to  7,800,000, 
a  decrease  of  5,400,000.  To  bring  the  1938  volume  up  to  the  1937  level  a  69.23% 
increase  would  have  been  needed.  Since  steel  has  at  best  an  elasticity  of  1,  it 
would  have  been  necessary  to  drop  the  price  at  least  to  a  point  where  13,200,000 
tons  would  have  brought  in  the  same  amount  of  dollars  as  the  7,800,000  tons  did 
at  1938  prices.  Since  the-  total  sales,  as  distinguished  from  other  revenues, 
amounted  to  $560,508,000  in  1938,  the  $71.86  sales  per  weighted  ton  would  have  to 
have  been  reduced  to  $560,508,000  divided  by  13,200,000,  or  $42.46  per  weighted 
ton.  This  represents  a  price  decrease  of  40.9%.  Disregarding  the  possibility 
that  other  operations  might  not  expand  with  increased  shipments  and  adding 
in  the  full  $5.80  per  weighted  ton  realized  from  other  operations  under  actual 
1938  conditions,  the  total  sales  and  operating  revenues  would  then  have  amounted 
to  $48.26  per  weighted  ton.  Since  the  variable  cash  costs  amount  to  $53.36  per 
weighted  ton,  the  Corporation  would  have  sustained  a  cash  loss  of  $5.10  on  every 
weighted  ton  sold  in  addition  to  failing  to  recover  any  part  of  the  fixed  cash  costs 
of  $152,600,000.  Assuming  that  the  price  reduction  would  have  been  successful 
in  restoring  the  1937  volume,  13,200,000  weighted  tons  would  have  been  sold. 
At  a  loss  of  $5.10  a  ton,  the  variable  cash  costs  that  would  not  have  been  covered 
by  the  sales  price  would  amount  to  $67,320,000.  Adding  in  the  $152,600,000 
fixed  costs  not  covered  by  the  sales  price,  the  Corporation  would  have  had  a 
cash  loss  for  the  year  of  $219,920,000.  This  is  without  making  any  provision  for 
the  depreciation  and  depletion  of  the  fixed  assets  of  the  Corporation  and  its  sub- 
sidiaries. The  average  working  capital  of  the  Corporation  for  the  year  1938 
amounted  to  $397,241,615."  Hence,  the  drain  of  such  a  cash  loss  upon  the  Cor- 
poration would  have  exhausted  its  working  capital  in  less  than  two  years.  If 
the  amount  of  the  depreciation  and  depiction  of  assets  at  this  volume  of  operations, 
amounting  to  $60,784,000,  is  added  to  the  cash  loss,  there  is  a  total  loss  of 
$280,704,000.  Annual  losses  at  this  rate  would  wipe  out  the  combined  equity 
of  the  preferred  and  common  stockholders  as  of  December  31,  1938,  in  about 
four  and  a  half  years. 


»For  computation  of  average  working  capital,  see  Appendix  I. 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER       14063 

Probably  such  drastic  decreases,  however,  are  not  contemplated  by  those  who 
criticize  the  steel  industry  for  failing  to  reduce  prices.  While  a  smaller  decrease, 
in  price  could  not  have  been  expected  under  any  circumstances  to  raise  the  1938 
volume  to  the  1937  level,  it  may  nevertheless  be  contended  that  some  price 
reduction  and  some  resulting  stimulation  in  volume  were  desirable.  The  facts 
are  that  any  further  price  reduction  in  1938  would  have  served  but  to  increase 
the  loss  sustained.  Chart  15  shows  the  actual  deficit  in  1938,  amounting  to 
$8,758,572  after  the  deduction  of  bond  interest  but  before  the  Federal  income  and 
profits  taxes  and  exclusive  of  non-operating  income  and  expense.  Added  thereto 
are  the  amounts  of  additional  deficit  that  would  have  been  incurred  if  various 
percentage  reductions  in  price  had  been  made,  assuming  that  steel  has  an  elasticity 
of  demand  of  1.  For  instance,  even  a  1  %  reduction  in  price  would  have  increased 
the  1938  loss  by  well  over  $3,000,000,  while  a  10%  reduction  in  price  would  have 
resulted  in  an  additional  loss,  after  allowing  for  the  maximum  probable  increase 
in  volume,  of  over  $43,000,000.  To  the  extent  that  the  assumed  increases  in 
volume  might  have  failed  to  result  from  the  decreases  in  price,  of  course,  the 
additional  losses  would  have  been  greater.  The  figures  on  which  the  chart  is 
■  based,'  together  with  the  additions  to  the  1938  deficit  which  would  have  taken 
place  if  prices  had  been  reduced  and  no  increase  in  volume  resulted,  are  shown  in 
Table  32. 

Table  32.— Estimated  Additions  to  1938  Deficit— How  Deficit  Would  Have  In- 
creased if  Average  1938  Prices  Had  Been  Reduced  Various  Percentages — United 
States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Percentage 
Reduction 
in  Price 


Estimated  Ad- 
ditional Loss, 
Assuming  ElaS' 

ticity  of  De- 
mand for  Steel 
ofl 


$3,900,000 
7,900,000 
12, 000, 000 
16, 200, 000 
20, 600, 000 
24,900,000 
29, 300, 000 
33,900,000 
38, 500, 000 
43,300,000 


Estimated  Ad- 
ditional Loss,  if 
No  Increase  in 
Volume  Re- 
sulted from 
Price  Reduc- 
tion 


$5,  600, 
11, 200, 
16, 800, 
22, 400, 
28,000, 
33,  600, 
39,200, 
44,800, 
50,400, 
66, 100, 


Percentage 
Reduction 
in  Price 


Estimated  Ad- 
ditional Loss, 
Assuming  Elas 

ticity  of  De- 
mand for  Steel 
ofl 


97, 


100, 000 
100,000 
200,000 
400,000 
700,000 
200,000 
800,000 
500,000 
400,000 
400,000 


Estimated  Ad- 
tional  Loss,  if 
No  Increase  in 
Volume  Re- 
sulted from 
Price  Reduc- 
tion 


$61,  700, 000 
67, 300, 000 
72,900,000 
78, 500, 000 
84, 100, 000 
89, 700, 000 
95, 300, 000 
100, 900, 000 
106, 600, 000 
112, 100, 000 


The  relationship  between  steel  prices,  volume  and  costs  for  the  United  States 
Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  is  such  that  the  probable  increase  in  volume 
which  would  result  from  a  price  decrease  is  never  as  great  as  the  increase  which 
would  be  required  to  compensate  for  the  reduced  amount  received  per  ton.  For 
instance,  the  relationship  between  the  average  1938  prices  and  costs  is  illustrated 
in  Chart  16.  This  chart  reveals  that  the  total  sales  and  revenues  at  1938  prices 
would  cover  all  of  the  costs  only  if  production  amounted  to  8.31  milHons  of  weighted 
tons  of  product  or  more.  The  dashed  sales  line  shows  the  total  sales  and  revenue 
that  would  be  realized  if  the  prices  at  which  the  products  were  sold  were  reduced 
10%  without  making  any  red'uction  in  the  rates  charged  in  the  transportation 
and  miscellaneous  operations.  It  should  be  noted  that  with  this  reduction  in 
price,  production  would  have  to  reach  12.36  millions  of  weighted  tons  to  break 
even.8  This  represents  an  increase  in  volume  of  48.8%  required  to  compensate 
for  the  decreased  prices.  The  same  relationship  holds  not  only  with  regard  to 
the  break-even  point,  but  also  to  the  netting  of  any  particular  amount  of  profit 
or  loss.  For  instance,  if  production  amounted  to  6,000,000  weighted  tons,  the 
loss  at  1938  average  prices  would  be  about  $50,500,000.  If  1938  prices  were 
decreased  10%,  volume  would  have  to  be  raised  48.8%,  or  to  about  8,925,000 
weighted  tons,  in  order  not  to  increase  the  loss. 

In  Table  33  are  shown  and  on  Chart  17  are  graphed  the  percentage  increases  in 
volume  that  would  be  required  to  compensate  for  various  percentage  decreases 
from  the  1938  average  prices  as  compared  with  the  maximum  probable  increase  in 
volume  that  would  result  from  a  price  decrease.'  This  probable  increase  i  ';ased 
on  the  assumption  that  the  elasticity  of  the  demand  for  steel  is  1.  As  hac  been 
mentioned  above,  aU  the  evidence  indicates  that  this  is  a  most  optimistic  estimate 
and  that  the  real  figure  is  considerably  smaller. 

'  For  method  of  computation,  see  Appendix  in. 

»  See  Appendix  IV  for  computation  of  break-even  points. 

»  See  Appendix  V  for  method  of  computation. 


14064 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Chart  15 


ESTIMATED  ADDITIONS  TO  1938  DEFICIT 

HOW  DEFICIT  WOULD  HAVE  INCREASED  IF  PRICES  HAD  BEEN  REDUCED 
AND  VOLUME  HAD  INCREASED  TO  SAME  RELATIVE  EXTENT 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
% 


672 


2     3    4     5    6     7    8    9    10  n  12  13   14  15  16  17   18 
PERCENTAGE  REDUCTION  IN  1938  AVERAGE  PRICE 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14065 


Chart  16 


RELATIONSHIP  BETWEEN  SALES  AND  COSTS 

EFFECT  OF  REDUCTION  FROM  AVERAGE  1938  PRICES 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 


1200 

1     1     1     1     1     1    1 

- 

^ 

2 

r 

V 

1 

1200 

1100 

c=i  SIM£S  AND  REVENUES 

<1938  PRICES) 
c«=»  SALES  AND  REVENUES 
11938  PRICtS  USS  10») 

1100 

1000 
900 
800 
700 
600 
500 
400 
300 
200 
100 
0 

1000 

900 

800 

700 

600 

/ 

F 

1 

1 

'^ 

1 

B 

EAK 

EVi 

i" 

^ 

" 

r 

1 

t 

V:: 

is 

1 

is 

1 
1 

•5« 

m 
m 

0r 
11 

\ 

\ 

^ 

% 

/ 

11 

~ 

liW 

i 

'■■. 

i 

1 

if- 

iii' 

■Si 

1 

/ 

<| 

■S 

TO 

AL 

m 

1 

" 

'f^ 

400 

/ 

/ 

i 

1 

M 

M  0i: 

:;;:; 

'M 

1 

300 
200 
100 
0 

/ 

/( 

% 

1 

;i 

1 

SI 

M 

IBM 

1 

■:-SI 

i 

1 

4 

'/ 

;■■■ 

B:-  M 

M' 

1 

1 

1 

/ 

r 

'; 

... 

.,  „ 

If 

2^ 

i 

-: 

m 

0     1     2    3    4     5    6     7     8     9    10  II   12   13  14  15  16  17  18 

MILUONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL 

TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 


NOTE:  COSTS  ARE  BASED  ON  19271938  DPERIENCE.  ADJUSTED  TO  1938  CONDITIONS 


14066 


CX)NCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  17 


INCREASES  IN  VOLUME  NEEDED  TO  COMPENSATE  FOR 

VARIOUS  DECREASES  IN  1938  PRICES 

COMPARED  TO  PROBABLE  RESULTING  INCREASES  IN  VOLUME 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

240 


0    1    2    3    4    5    6    7    8    9   10  11  12  13  14  15  16  17  18  19  20  21 
PERCENTAGE  DECREASES  FROM  AVERAGE  1938  PRICES 


NOTt:    PROSABU  RESULTING  INCREASES  IN  VOLUME  EfSED  IM  ASSUMPTION  THAT  ELASTIQTY  OF  DEW^NO  EQUALS  1 


TaSle  33. — Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Various  Decreases  in 
Average  1938  Prices — Compared  to  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume — 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Percentage  Reduc- 
tion in  Price 

Percentage 

Increase  in 

Voltune 

Needed 

Probable 
Percentage 
Increase, 
Assuming 
Elasticity  of  1 

Percentage  Reduc- 
tion in  Price 

Percentage 

Increase  m 

Volume 

Needed 

Probable 
Percentage 
Increase, 
Assuming 
Elasticity  ofl 

3.4 
7.0 
10.9 
15,1 
19.6 
24.5 
29.8 
35.5 
41.8 

1.0 
2.0 
3.1 
4.2 
5.3 
6.4 
7.5 
8.7 
9.9 

10 

48.8 
56.-4 
64.8 
74.2 
84.8 
96.7 
190.3 
453.6 
5858.2 

11.1 

12.4 

12    . 

13.6 

14.0 

16.3 

15 

17.7 

20 

25.0 

25 

33.3 

42.9 

Since  the  average  1938  prices  represent  the  average  results  of  prices  in  effect 
before  and  after  the  June  24,  1938  price  reduction,  a  similar  analysis  to  that  made 
above  has  been  made  with  the  total  sales  and  revenue  line  reduced  to  what  it 
would  have  been  if  the  prices  prevailing  in  the  second  half  of  1938,  after  the  price 
reduction,  had  prevailed  the  entire  year. 


OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER        14067 

The  total  sales  and  revenue  line  at  the  prices  prevailing  in  the  second  half  of 
1938  was  computed  by  adjusting  the  sales  component  of  the  total  sales  and 
revenue  per  weighted  ton  computed  above,  on  the  basis  of  the  selling  value  of 
rolled  and  finished  steel  products  sold  during  the  second  half  of  1938,  as  compared 
to  the  average  selling  value  of  these  products  for  the  entire  year.  The  f.  o.  b. 
selling  value  of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  sold  each  month  was  obtained 
from  the  Comptroller's  Department  of  the  Corporation.  The  total  selling  value 
of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  for  the  last  six  months  of  the  year,  divided  by 
the  weighted  tonnage  of  such  products  shipped  during  that  period,  gives  the 
average  amount  per  weighted  ton  received  after  the  June  24,  1938  price  reduction. 
The  selling  value  for  the  entire  year,  divided  by  the  weighted  tonnage  shipped 
during  the  entire  year,  furnishes  the  average  amount  received  per  weighted  ton 
of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  for  the  year  as  a  whole.  The  $71.86  referred 
to  above  as  the  sales  per  weighted  ton  of  tonnage  product^  shipped  represents  the 
amount  received  for  all  products  sold  per  weighted  ton  of  all  tonnage  products 
shipped.  Multiplying  this  figure  by  the  ratio  of  the  average  steel  price  computed 
above  for  the  last  half  of  1938  to  the  average  price  for  1938  as  a  whole,  gives 
an  estimate  of  the  total  sales  per  weighted  ton  of  products  if  the  same  propor- 
tionate reductions  in  the  prices  of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  that  were  in 
effect  in  the  second  half  of  1938  had  been  applied  to  all  products  sold  and  had  been 
put  into  effect  at  the  beginning  of  the  year.  The  computation,  made  in  Table 
34,  shows  that  the  sales  per  weighted  ton  would  then  be  $67.33.  Adding  to  this 
the  $5.80  per  weighted  ton  arising  from  miscellaneous  transportation  operations, 
the  estimated  total  annual  sales  and  revenues  per  weighted  ton  at  prices  prevailing 
after  the  June  24,  1938  price  reduction  would  be  $73.13. 

Table  34. — Estimate  of  Annual  Sales  and  Revenue  at  Prices  Prevailing  in  Second 
Half  of  1938 — United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Period 

F.  0.  B.  Selling 
Value  of  Rolled 
and  Finished 
Steel  Products 
Shipped " 

Weighted  Tons 

of  Rolled  and 

Finished  Steel 

Products 

Shipped  I 

SeUing  Value 

Per  Weighted 

Ton 

$230,  750,  804 
246,835,450 

3,087,392 
3,798,057 

$74. 74 

July  to  Dec  ,  1938 

64  99 

Year  1938 

$477.  586. 254 

6,885,449 

$69  36 

Item 

1938  Average 

Per  Weighted 

Ton 

Adjustment 

Second  Half 

1938  Average 

Per  Weighted 

Ton 

Sales 

$71.86 
5.80 

64.99/69.36 

Total  Rftlps  ftnd  RflVftniifif! 

$77. 66 

$73  13 

1  Before  yearly  adjustment  lor  returns  and  allowances,  amounting  to  $4,732,196  and  3,504  unweighted  tons. 

Table  35. — Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Various  Decreases  in 
2nd  Half,  1938,  Prices  Compared  to  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume — 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Percentage  Reduc- 
tion in  Price 

Percentage 

Increase  in 

Volume 

Needed 

Probable 
Percentage 
Increase, 
Assuming 
Elasticity  of  1 

Percentage  Reduc- 
tion in  Price 

Percentage 

Increase  in 

Volume 

Needed 

Probable 
Percentae 
Increase 
Assuming 
Elasticity  of  1 

4.0 
8.4 
13.1 
18.3 
24.0 
30.2 
37.2 
44.8 
53.5 

1.0 
2.0 
3.1 
4.2 
6.3 
6.4 
7.5 
8.7 
9.9 

10 

63.1 
74.1 
86.7 
101.3 
118.3 
138.4 
342,6 
2984.4 

11 

12  4 

12 

13  6 

15 

17  7 

20 

25  0 

9 

14068 


aONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


Chart  18  shows  the  price,  cost,  and  volume  relationship  under  prices  prevailing 
in  the  second  half  of  1938.  Here  again  the  revenues  at  higher  volumes  have  been 
overstated  to  the  extent  that  the  transportation  and  miscellaneous  revenues 
might  drop  below  $5.80  per  weighted  ton  if  shipments  were  increased.  Never- 
theless it  may  be  noted  that  the  break-even  point  at  these  prices  is  10.47  millions 
of  weighted  tons,  as  compared  with  8.31  millions  of  weighted  tons  at  the  average 
1938  prices.  Similarly,  a  10%  decrease  in  the  second  half  of  1938  prices  would 
be  offset  only  if  volume  were  increased  63.1%  to  17.1  millions  of  weighted  tons. 
This  would  mean  that  the  Corporation  would  have  to  operate  at  an  average  of 
over  90%  of  capacity  for  the  entire  year  in  order  to  break  even.  Table  35  and 
Chart  19  show  the  percentage  increase  in  volume  required  to  compensate  for 
various  decreases  in  the  second  half  of  1938  prices  'o  as  compared  to  the  increase 
in  volume  that  would  result  from  the  drop  in  prices  if  the  elasticity  of  demand  for 
steel  were  as  high  as  1." 

In  connection  with  the  break-even  point,  it  has  been  contended  that  in  a  truly 
competitive  arrangement  the  break-even  point  will  be  only  a  little  bit  short  of 
capacity.  It  has  already  been  shown  that  if  the  prices  prevailing  in  the  second 
half  of  1938  were  reduced  by  10%,  the  break-even  point  for  the  Corporation  and 
its  subsidiaries  would  be  moved  up  to  over  90%  capacity.  The  effect  of  this  high 
break-even  point  on  the  possible  return  on  investment  that  might  be  realized  by 
the  Corporation  may  be  seen  by  calculating  the  rate  of  operation  that  would  have 
to  be  maintained  to  realize  an  average  return  as  modest  as  5%  on  the  entire 
tangible  investment.  The  average  investment  of  the  Steel  Corporation,  consist- 
ing of  the  combined  interests  of  stockholders  and  bondholders,  after  eliminating 
all  intangible  values,  for  the  year  1938  amounted  to  $1,586,523,686.  A  5% 
return  on  this  investment  would  require  a  profit  before  bond  interest  of  over 
$79,300,000.  Deducting  bond  interest  of  $8,300,000,  this  leaves  a  profit  after 
bond  interest  of  over  $71,000,000  to  be  obtained.  Even  if  Federal  income  taxes 
are  disregarded,  to  realize  such  a  profit  at  prices  10%  below  second  half  of  1938 
prices,  which  would  be  low  enough  to  put  the  break-even  point  at  around  90%  of 
capacity,  the  Corporation  would  have  to  operate  throughout  the  year  at  an  aver- 
age rate  of  over  130%  of  capacity,  an  obvious  impossibility. '^ 

VI.  Weighted  Tonnages  and  the  Operating  Rate 

The  operating  rate  for  the  subsidiaries  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation, 
as  ordinarily  computed  and  as  published  in  the  annual  reports,  is  obtained  by 
dividing  the  total  number  of  tons  of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  produced 
by  the  estimated  capacity  in  tons  for  producing  rolled  and  finished  steel  products. 
This  figure  has  its  limitations  as  an  indicator  of  steel  producing  activities.  For 
instance,  the  production  of  a  million  tons  of  sheets,  with  all  the  processing  that 
they  require,  would  involve  considerably  more  activity  than  the  production  of 
the  same  quantity  of  rails,  which  are  more  simple  to  produce,  yet  either  would 
result  in  the  same  operating  rate. 

>»  See  Appendix  V  for  method  of  computation. 

"  While  the  assumption  of  any  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  greater  than  1  is  highly  unrealistic,  it  is 
interesting  to  note  that  even  if  steel  had  an  elasticity  of  1.5  or  2,  the  percentage  increase  in  volume  needed  to 
offset  a  price  reduction  would  still  greatly  exceed  the  percentage  increase  in  volume  which  would  then 
result  from  reducing  prices: 


Decrease  in  Price 


1%- 
2%- 
3%. 
4%. 

5% 
10% 
15% 

30% 


Resulting  Increase  in  Volume 


1.5% 
3.1% 
4.7% 
6.3% 

i?:?l 

'27.6% 
39.8% 
54.0% 
70.8% 


If  Elasticity  =2 


2.0% 
4.1% 
6.3% 
8.5% 
11. 1% 
23.  5% 


77.  f 
104.1 


Increase  in  Volume  Needed  to 
Offset: 


Decrease  in 
Average  1938 
Steel  Prices 


3.4% 
7.0% 
10.9% 
15.1% 
19,  6% 
48.8% 
96.7% 
190. 3% 
453.6% 
5858.2% 


Decrease  in 

Second  Half 

1938  Steel  Prices 


8.4% 

13.1% 

18.3% 

24. 0% 

63.1% 

138.4% 

342. 6% 

2984.4% 

(No  increase 

sufficient) 


'  'See  Appendix  VI  for- computations  involved. 


OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  18 


14069 


RELATIONSHIP  BETWEEN  SALES  AND  COSTS 

EFFECT  OF  REDUCTION  FROM  2nd  HALF  1938  PRICES 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

1100  - 
1000  - 
900  - 

CO 

^     800  - 

-J 

o     700- 

0  600- 

1  500- 

i     ^- 

300- 

200? 

100 

0 

I       1       1       1       1       1       1 

// 

1 

°     8     8     8     i     §     8     8     8      i     1     i     ^ 

MILLIONS    OF    DOLLARS 

( 1  SALES  AND  REVENUES 

•  Jno  H«.f  19M  PRICtS. 
c»=.  SALES  AND  REVENUES      ' 

/ 

-> 

- 

■^ 

y 

n 

-^■:> 

1 

^^^';M'-'' 

\| 

// 

f^ 

v/ 

Y 

4 

yf 

■ 

/ 

i  ^ 

1      i 
it 

/ 

7 

h  1 

ill! 

/ 

/ 

^^ 

f 

r 

TO 

TAL 

COSTSJ    . 

/ 

I 

m 

■:. 

'% 

% 

lift 

i 

M 

i! 

1; 

1 

i 

i'y.  'M 

i 

1 

% 

1 

1 

11 

II 

m 

M 

■':-^^ 

is 

Si 

• 

0     1     2     3     4     5    6     7     8     9    10  11    12   13  14   15  16  17  18 

MILUONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  AU 

TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

NOTE.   COSTS  ARE  BASED  ON  19271938  EXPERIENCE.  ADJUSTED  TO  1938  CONOmONS 

Table  36. — Weighted  Tonnages  of  All  Tonnage  Products  and  Unweighted  Tonnages 
of  Rolled  and  Finished  Products  Shipped — United  States  Steel  Corporation  and 
Subsidiaries 


Year 

Weighted  Tois 

All  Tonnage 

Products 

Shipped 

Actual  Tons 
Rolled  and  Fin- 
ished Products 
Shipped 

Year 

Weighted  Tons 

All  Tonnage 

Products 

Shipped 

Actual  Tons 

Rolled  and  Fin 

ished  Products 

Shipped 

1927 

13,008,520 
13,994,239 
15,088,968 
11,934,595 
8,130,577 
4,352.016 

12,993,283 
13.973,129 
15, 234,  355 
11, 624,  294 
7,  676,  744 
3,974,062 

1933 

6, 160,  338 
6,096,937 
7,631,783 
11,012,458 
13, 186.  548 
7,758,891 

1928 

1934 

5  911  760 

1929 

1935 

.  71356!  185 
10  784  716 

1930. 

1936 

1931 

1937  

12.789.841 
6,659,253 

1932 

1938 

In  making  this  study  of  the  relation  of  cost  to  volume  it  was  apparent  that  the 
cost  of  producing  a  million  tons  of  rails,  for  instance,  would  be  lower  than  the  cost 
of  producing  a  million  tons  of  sheets.  For  this  reason,  as  has  already  been  men- 
tioned, the  tonnages  of  each  type  of  product  shipped  were  weighted  on  the  basis 
of  the  average  miU  cost  for  that  type  of  product.  Both  the  subdivisions  of  rolled 
and  finished  steel  products  and  the  main  classifications  of  tonnage  products  other 
than  steel  were  weighted  by  the  ratio  of  their  average  mill  cost  to  the  average 


14070 


OONCJ-ENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  19 


INCREASES  IN  VOLUME  NEEDED  TO  COMPENSATE  FOR 

VARIOUS  DECREASES  IN  2nd  HALF  1938  PRICES 

COMPARED  TO  PROBABLE  RESULTING  INCREASES  IN  VOLUME 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  ANO  SUBSIDIARIES 

440 


400 


360 

ui 

§    320 

J    280 

^    240 

q: 
o 
5    200 


o 

S    120 


40 


]. 

n 

- 

1 

' 

' 

„             IN   HLfi 
IN  VOL 

SES 
UME 

_nnO       1- 

.mmM 

nl        [•  

t±x:::t:i::..l.. 

PRODABU 
.  RESULTING 
INCREASES 
IN  VOLUME 


1  2  3  4  5  6  7  8  9  10  U  12  13  14  15  16  17  18  19  20  21 
PERCENTAGE  DECREASES  IN  PRICES 


NOTE:    Pm>8ABL£  RESULTING  INCREASES  IN  VOLUME  BASED  IN  ASSUMPTION  THAT  ELASTICITY  Of  DEMAND  EQUALS  I 


mill  cost  of  all  rolled  and  finished  products.  In  this  way  the  actual  tonnages 
shipped  each  year  were  converted  to  equivalent  tons  of  average  cost  rolled  and 
finished  steel  products.  Accordingly,  the  break-even  point  at  various  price  levels 
has  been  stated  in  terms  of  weighted  tonnages  anH  it  is  essential  to  keep  in  mind 
the  relationship  between  these  weighted  tonnage  Lgures  and  the  regular  operating 
rate  figures  if  the  significance  of  the  weighted  tonnage  figures  is  to  be  properly 
appreciated. 

Table  36  shows  the  unweighted  tonnages  of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products 
shipped  each  year,  together  with  the  corresponding  weighted  tonnages  of  all 
tonnage  products.  The  weighted  and  unweighted  tonnages  are  plotted  in  rela- 
tion to  each  other  on  Chart  20.  Inspection  of  the  chart  shows  that  the  points 
for  each  year  fall  very  nearly  in  a  straight  line  but  that  as  the  unweighted  tonnages 
decrease,  the  weighted  tonnages  do  not  decrease  quite  so  rapidly,  indicating  that 
in  slack  years  the  sales  of  heavy,  low-cost  steel  products  fall  ofif  relatively  more 
than  the  sales  of  the  lighter,  high-cost  items  and  of  the  products;;other  than  steel. 
Computation  of  the  line  of  average  relationship  by  the  least  squares  method 
shows  that  the  weighted  tonnage  is  generally  95.36%  of  the  unweighted  tonnage 
plus  742,000  tons.  This  would  indicate  that  if  the  shipments  of  rolled  and  finished 
steel  products  reached  the  January  1st,  1939  capacity  of  approximately  17,940,000 
tons,  the  corresponding  weighted  tonnage  snipped  would  amount  to  about 
17,850,000  weighted  tons.  On  the  basis  of  the  average  relationship  existing  be- 
tween weighted  and  unweighted  tonnages  at  various  shipment  levels,  it  is  possible 
to  compute  the  weighted  tonnages  and  the  percent  of  capacity  operated  based  on 
weighted  tonnages,  which  would  be  equivalent  to  various  operating  rates  as  ordi- 
narily computed.     The  results  of  this  computation  are  tabulated  in  Table  37 


OONOENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  20 


14071 


REL/ 
SH 

18 

g     14 
g      12 

|.« 
1    ' 

2      6 

i   * 

2 
0 

ITION  OF  ACTUAL  TONS  OF  ROLLED  AND  FINISHED  STEEL  PRODUCTS 
IPPED  AND  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

/- 

16 

14     § 

12      £ 

8       ^ 

6             Q 

2       ^ 
0 

1928 

,x''' 

iT929 

"fr- 

1937.   / 

-V 

.>* 

1931 

y,^ 

""«f 

Z' 

f^a. 

"?. 

^/ 

X 

<^ 

-^ 

CAPACirr.  JAN. 

__  1       1   _ 

1.193 

1 

C 

1      2      3     4      5     6      7     8      9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16    17    18 
ACTUAL  TONS  -  ROLLED  AND  FINISHED  PRODUCTS 

Table  37.- 


-  Average  Weighted  Equivalent  of  Unweighted  Tonnages — United  State 
Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Actual  Tons 

Rolled  and 

Finished 

Products 

(Millions  of 

Tons) 

Percent  of 

1/1/39 
Capacity 

Average 
Equivalent 
Weighted 
Tonnage  of  All 
Products 
(Millions  of 
Tons) 

Percent  of 

Estimated 

1/1/39  Weighted 

Capacity 

.90 

5 

1.60 

9.0 

1.79 

10 

2.45 

13.7 

2.69 

15 

3.31 

18.5 

3.59 

20 

4.17 

23.4 

4.49 

25 

5.02 

28.1 

5.38 

30 

6.87  . 

32.9 

6.28 

35 

6.73 

37.7 

7.18 

40 

7.59 

42.5 

8.07 

45 

8.44 

47.3 

8.97 

50 

9.30 

52.1 

9.87 

55 

10.15 

56.9 

10.76 

60 

11.00 

61.6 

11.60 

65 

11.86 

66.4 

12.56 

70 

12.72 

71.? 

13.46 

75 

13.58 

76.1 

14.35 

80 

14.43 

80.9 

15.25 

85 

15.28 

85.6 

16.15 

90 

16.14 

90.4 

17.04 

95 

16.99 

95.2 

17.94 

100 

17.85 

100.0 

It  should  be  noted,  however,  that  all  of  the  points  on  Chart  20  do  not  fall 
exactly  on  the  average  line.  These  variations  from  year  to  year  constitute  one 
reason  for  using  weighted  rather  than  unweighted  tonnages  in  making  this  study. 
To  the  extent  that  the  relationship  between  weighted  and  unweighted  tonnages 
in  ar\y  year  is  different  from  the  average  relationship  for  the  volume  involved, 
the  equivalent  weighted  tonnage  figures  given  in  Table  37  will  be  inaccurate. 
Since  this  variance  in  relationship  betweei  weighted  and  unweighted  tonnages 
arises  from  differing  proportions  of  each  type  of  product  constituting  the  total 
sales,  the  amount  of  the  variance  becomes  more  limited  as  operations  approach 


14072        OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

capacity,  since  at  capacity  the  proportions  are  fixed  by  the  capacity  for  producing 
each  type  of  product. 

Table  38. — Ratio  of  Tons  of  Rolled  and  Finished  Products  to  Weighted  Tons  of 
All  Tonnage  Products — United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Year 

Unweighted 

Tons  Rolled 

and  Finished 

Products 

Shipped 

Weighted  Tons 

All  Tonnage 

Products 

Ratio 
Unweighted 
to  Weighted 

1927 

12.99 
13.97 
15.23 

3!9V 
5.81 
5.91 
7.36 
10.78 
12.79 
6.66 

13.01 
13.99 
15.09 
11.93 
8.13 
4.35 
6,16 
6.10 
7.63 
11.01 
13.19 
7.76 

0  9985 

1928 

0  9986 

1929 

1  0093 

1930 

0  9740 

1931 

0  9446 

1932 

0  9126 

0  9432 

1934 

0.9689 

1935 

0.9646 

1936 

0. 9791 

1937 

0.9697 

1938 

0.8582 

Since  the  variations  from  average  do  not  show  up  very  clearly  in  Chart  20, 
the  percentage  of  weighted  tons  of  all  tonnage  products  shipped  represented  by 
unweighted  tons  of  rolled  and  finished  products  is  computed  in  Table  38.  The 
resulting  data  are  graphed  on  Chart  21.  Here  again  it  becomes  apparent  that 
the  actual  tonnages  tend  to  be  smaller  than  the  weighted  tonnages  when  operating 
rates  are  low.  Deviations  of  the  individual  points  from  the  line  of  average  rela- 
tionship, however,  are  considerable.  In  1938,  for  instance,  the  ratio  of  the 
unweighted  tonnages  shipped  to  the  weighted  tonnages  was  even  smaller  than 
would  be  expected  on  the  basis  of  the  average  relationship  on  which  Table  37  is 
based.  Thus  the  1938  shipments  of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products,  amounting 
to  6.66  millions  of  unweighted  tons  or  37.1%  of  January  1st,  1939,  capacity, 
would  normally  be  expected  to  equal  7.09  miUions  of  weighted  tons  of  all  tonnage 
products,  or  39.7%  of  weighted  capacity.     As  a  matter  of  fact,  however,  the 

Chart  21 


RATIO  OF  TONS  OF  ROLLED  AND  FINISHED  PRODUCTS  TO  WEIGHTED  TONS 

OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  AT  DIFFERENT  ROLLED  AND  FINISHED 

SHIPMENT  LEVELS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 


5 

1928 

^ 

- 

-• 

1935 

^ 

.936 

1930 

1927: 
1937 

,^ 

19^ 

- 

>»l^ 

--1 

31 

-^ 

1938 

' 

^ 

1      2      3     4      5     6      7    -8     9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16    17    18 
UNWEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ROLLED  AND  RNISHED  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14073 


weighted  tonnage  in  1938  amounted  to  7.76  millions  of  weighted  tons,  or  43.4% 
of  weighted  capacity.  This  indicates  that  no  percentage  of  capacity  as  ordinarily 
computed  can  be  named  as  the  break-even  point,  since  the  exact  percentage  at 
which  the  Corporation  would  break  even  will  depend  upon  the  type  of  products 
composing  the  total  products  sold,  and  these  vary  considerably  from  year  to 
year,  even  when  total  shipments'  are  approximately  the  same. 

Some  of  the  year  to  year  variations  in  the  relation  between  the  weighted  ton- 
nages of  all  tonnage  products  and  the  unweighted  tonnages  of  rolled  and  finished 
products  shipped  are  accounted  for  by  variations  in  the  percentage  of  light  and 
heavy  steel  products  shipped,  and  others  by  the  amount  of  products  other  than 
steel  which  are  sold.  In  order  that  the  causes  of  the  variations  may  be  observed, 
the  percentage  relationships  between  the  unweighted  tonnages  of  each  class  of 
products  shipped  and  the  total  tonnage  of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products 
shipped  are  given  in  Table  39.  Notice  should  be  taken  of  the  fact,  however,  that 
the  apparent  increase  in  the  tonnage  of  sundry  materials  and  by-products  sold  in 
1938  is  partly  the  result  of  including  in  sales,  cost  of  goods  sold,  and  sundry 
materials  and  by-products,  shipped,  the  sales  of  crushed  slag.  In  prior  years  the 
net  proceeds  from  the  sale  of  this  item  were  included  in  miscellaneous  income. 
The  total  tonnage  of  sundry  materials  and  by-products  in  1938  would  amount  to 
6.3%  of  the  tonnage  of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products  shipped,  if  computed 
on  the  same  basis  as  in  prior  j^ears. 

Table  39. — Percentage  of  Tons  of  Various  Classes  of  Products  Shipped  to  Total 
Tons  of  Rolled  and  Finished  Products  Shipped— 1927-1938— United  States  Steel 
Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Class  of  Product 


Semi-Finished 

Rails. ._ 

Plates 

Heavy    Structural 

Shapes 

Merchant  Bar,  H.  R. 

Strip,  Hoops,-etc.-.. 
Sheets,  Black  and  Tin 

Plate 

Cold  Rolled  Strip,  Wire 

and  Wire  Products- 
Copper  Products  and 

Insulated  Wires  and 

Cables 

Tubular  Products 

Fabricated  Structural 

Shapes 

Angle  Bars,  Tie  Plates 

and  All  Other  Rail 

Joints 

Total  1  to  10 

-\xles 

Wheels. 

Nuts,  Rivets,  Spikes, 

Bolts : 

Foundry  Products 

Special  Track  Work. .  . 

Sundry  Iron  and  Steel 

Products 

Totaintoie 

All  Rolled  and  Fin- 
ished Steel 

Pig  Iron,  Ingots,  Ferro 
and  Scrap 

Limestone,  Coal,  Coke 
and  Iron  Ore 

Sundry  Materials  and 
By-Products 

Total  Tons  of  All 
Products  Sold  on 
Tonnage  Basis 


Percentage  of  Total  Tons  of  Rolled  and  Finished  Products  Shipped 


1927     1928     1929 


0.3 
0.6 

0.5 

.  0.4 

0.2 

0.7 

2.7 


100.0 
1.8 


100.0 
2.5 


100.0 

2.8 
38.4 
3.6 


1931  1932  1933 


135.4  il45.5  144.8  ,133.5  134.0  137,6  144.9  145.2  139.3  141.2 


1936  1937  1938 


10.9 
.5.1 
6.8 

7.7 

17.3 

22.0 


9.6 
43.7 
15.2 


If  on,  same  basis  as  other  years,  would  be  6.3. 


14074 


QONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


In  order  that  the  efifect  of  variations  in  the  proportionate  amounts  of  each 
type  of  rolled  and  finished  products,  as  distinguished  from  variations  in  the 
proportionate  amount  of  products  other  than  rolled  and  finished  steel  products, 
may  be  further  shown,  Table  40  gives  the  unweighted  tonnages  of  rolled  and 
finished  products  shipped  each  year,  together  with  the  weighted  tonnages  of 
rolled-  and  finished  products  only,  exclusive  of  other  tonnage  products.  The 
graphing  of  these  data  on  Chart  22  shows  clearly  that  the  more  costly  light  prod- 
ucts constitute  a  higher  proportion  of  sales  in  slack  periods,  since  the  percentage 
of  weighted  tons  of  rolled  and  finished  products  represented  by  unweighted  tons 
falls  off  considerably  as  the  operating  rate  goes  down.  It  is  again  noticeable  that 
there  is  also  considerable  variance  in  the  relationship  between  weighted  and  un- 
weighted tonnages  of  rolled  and  finished  products  shipped  in  years  in  which  the 
unweighted  tonnages  were  approximately  similar.  For  example,  the  chart  shows 
that  in  the  year  1934  the  actual  tonnage  was  much  nearer  to  the  amount  of  the 
weighted  tonnage  than  would  be  expected  at  such  a  low  shipment  level.  The 
explanation  may  be  obtained  by  an  inspection  of  Table  39,  which  shows  that  in 
1934  rails,  plates  and  other  heavy,  lower  cost  products  constituted  almost  as  great 
a  percentage  of  the  total  shipments  as  in  years  when  the  operating  rate  v/as  much 
higher. 

Table  40. — Ratio  of  Unweighted  to  Weighted  Tons  of  Rolled  and  Finished  Products — 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Year 

Actual  Tons 
Rolled  and 
Finished 
Products 

Weighted 
Tons  Rolled 
and  Finished 

Products 

Ratio  Un- 
weighted to 
Weighted 

1927 

12.99 
13.97 
15.23 
11.62 

7.68 
5.97 
5.81 
5.91 

7.36 
10.79 
12.79 

6.66 

12.75 
13.62 
14.66 
11.51 

7.86 
4.23 
6.97 
5.89 

7.36 
10.47 
12.49 

6.89 

1. 0187 

1928 

1.0258 

1929 

1.0395 

1930 

1.0103 

1931. 

'932 : 

0.9766 
0. 9397 

li,33 

0. 9732 

1934 

1.0039 

1935 

0.9996 

1936 

1.0297 

1937 

1.0243 

1938 

0.9672 

All  in  all,  then,  it  may  be  said  that  the  weighted  tonnage  figures  arrived  at  in 
this  study  are  a  fairly  accurate  indication  of  the  true  break-even  point.  There  is 
not  a  sufficiently  constant  relationship  between  weighted  and  unweighted  ton- 
nages, however,  to  make  possible  an  accurate  conversion  of  the  break-even  point, 
expressed  in  weighted  tonnages,  to  a  break-even  point  expressed  in  terms  of  per- 
centage of  capacity  operated,  as  this  percentage  is  ordinarily  computed.  The 
conversion  made  in  Table  37  can  serve  as  a  rough  guide  and  nothing  more.  It 
indicates  that  the  break-even  point,  under  prices  prevailing  in  the  last  half  of 
1938,  of  approximately  ten  and  a  half  million  weighted  tons  would  represent  about 
55%  of  capacity  on  the  ordinary  basis.  If  the  preponderance  of  light  products 
that  prevailed  during  1938  recurred,  the  equivalent  unweighted  tonnage  would 
be  somewhat  lower,  reducing  the  break-even  point  to  about  50%.  Regardless  of 
this  variation,  the  entire  study  indicates  beyond  question  that  the  nature  of  the 
demand  for  steel  and  the  cost  pattern  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and 
its  subsidaries  are  such  that  the  increased  volume  of  sales  that  might  result  could 
not  compensate  for  a  general  price  reduction,  and  that  general  lowering  of  prices 
is  not  the  road  to  prosperity,  undiminished  employment,  and  undiminished  pay- 
rolls in  the  steel  industry. 


Appendix  I.  Computation  of  Average  Working  Capital- 

-1938 

Item 

Jan.  1,  1938 

Dec.  31,  1938 

Total 

$480,737,119.87 
117,331,070.84 

$510, 338, 510. 30 
79,  261, 328. 94 

$991,  075,  630. 17 

196,  592,  399. 78 

Working  Capital 

$363,406,049.03 

$J31, 077, 181.36 

$794,  483,  230.  39 

Average  Working  Capital 

$397,  241,  815. 19 

« 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 
Chart  22 


14075 


PER  CENT  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ROLLED  AND  FINISHED  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

REPRESENTED  BY  UNWEIGHTED  TONNAGES  OF  ROLLED  AND  FINISHED 

PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

U.  S  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

105 

100 

z 

Ui 

"       95 

a. 

90 

85 
80 

105 
100 

UJ 

95      " 
ee. 

UJ 

a. 
90 

85 
80 

1934^ 

1935 

.,36' 

^'' 

.93. 
930 

1927 

■^'^ 

_,- 

>9« 

^-- 

193* 

"' 

■^ 

' 

1932 

( 

)      1     2      3      4     5     6      7     8     9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16    17    18 
UNWEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ROLLED  AND  RNISHED  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

Appendix  II.  Computation  of  Percentage  Increase  in  Volume  to  be 
Expected  from  Percentage  Decrease* in  Price,  Assuming  Elasticity 
OF  Demand  for  Steel  op  1 

Let: 

p  =  price 

v  =  volume 

s  =  total  sales  in  dollars 

d  =  fractional  decrease  in  price 

i  =  fractional  increase  in  volume 

Then: 

(1)  pv=s 

If  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  is  1,  a  decrease  in  price  will  be  accompanied 
by  a  corresponding  increase  in  volume  sufficient  to  keep  the  total  sales  in 
dollars  unchanged. 

Hence: 

(2)  (p-pd)   (v  +  vi)=s 
■  Substituting  from  (1): 

(3)  (p-pd)   (v+vi)  =  pv 
Factoring: 

(4)  pv(l-d)   (l  +  i)=pv 
Dividing  by  pv  (1-d) : 

pv 

(5)  l  +  i= 


Simplifying: 
(6)  l  +  i= 


pv  (1-d) 

1 

1-d 


Subtracting  1  from  each  side  of  the  equation: 
1 

(7)  i= 1 

1-d 

12449] — 41— pt.  26 —32 


14076  aONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Simplifying: 

1 
(8)  i  = 


1-d 


1-d 
d 


1-d 


1-d 
Substituting  various  values  for  d : 


d 

1 

d 

i 

d 

i 

1  <■ 

: 

d 

i 

0.01 

0.0101 

0.11 

0.  1236 

0.21 

0.2658 

1  0.31 

0.  4493 

0.41  

0.  6949 

.02 

.0204 

.12 

.1364 

.22 

.2821 

.32 

.4706 

.42 

.7241 

.03 

.0309 

.13 

.1494 

.23 

.2987 

.4925 

.43 

.7544 

.04 

.0417 

.14 

.1628 

.24 

.3158 

.34. 

.5152 

.44 

.7857 

.05 

.0526 

.1,"; 

.1765 

.25 

.3333 

.35 

.5385 

.45 

.8182 

.06 _ 

.0638 

.16 

.1905 

.26 

.3514 

.36 

.  .5625 

.46 

.  8519 

.07 

.0753 

.17 

.2048 

.27 

.3699 

.37 

.5873 

.47 

.  8868 

.08 

.0870 

.]8 

.2195 

.28 

.  3889 

.38 

.6129 

.48 

.9231 

.09 

.0989 

.19 

.2346 

.29 

.4085 

.39 

.6393 

.49 

.9608 

.10 

"" 

.20 

.2500 

.30 

.4286 

.40 

.6667 

.50 

1.0000 

Appendix  III.  Actual  Operating  Deficit  in  1938  and  Estimated  Addition  to 
Deficit  if  Prices  Had  Been  Further  Reduced 

Actual  Operating  Deficit — 1938: 

Actual   Deficit   Before   Provision   for   Income   Taxes   but   after 

Interest,  as  per  Statement  to  F.  T.  C $4,  787,  454 

Non-Operating  Income: 

"Other  Income   (Net)",  as  per  Statement  to 

F.  T.  C $2,524,320 

Add:  Idle  Plant  Expenses  included  therein 2,  440,  185 


Subtract:    Discounts    on    Purchases    included 
therein 


4,  964,  505 
993,  387 


3,971,  118 


Actual  Operating  Deficit 8,  758,  572 

Estimated  Addition  to  Deficit  if  Prices  Had  Been  Further  Reduced: 
Given: 

1938  volume  =  7.8  millions  of  weighted  tons. 

Sales  at  1938  prices  =  $71.86  per  weighted  ton. 

1938  transportation  and  miscellaneous  revenues  =  $5. 80  per  weighted 

ton. 
Costs  =  $55,734  per  weighted  ton +  182.1  millions  of  dollars. 
Let: 

d  =  fractional  reduction  in  price. 
i  =  resulting  increase  in  volume. 
X  =  the  additional  loss  (in  millions  of  dollars). 
L=average  loss  at   1938  average  prices  and   volume   (in   millions  of 

dollars) . 
Li  =  average  loss  at  reduced  price  and  changed  volume  (in  millions  of 
dollars). 
Then: 

X  =  L,-L 

Since  los.ses  equal  costs  minus  sales  and  revenues: 
L  =  [55.734    (7.8)  +  182.1]-[71.86    (7.  8)  +  5.80    (7.8)]. 
L,  =  [55.734  (7.8)  (l  +  i)  +  182.1]-[71.86  (1-d)   (7.8)   (1  +  0  +  5.80  (7.8) 
,      (l  +  i)l 
Removing  brackets  and  simplifving  (2): 
L  =  55.734  (7.81  +  182.1-71.86   (7.8) -5.80  (7.8) 
L=  182.1 -21.926  (7.8) 
L=  11.077 

Removing  brackets  and  simplifving  (3): 
L,  =  55.734   (7.8)    (1  +  i)  + 182.1 -71.86   (1-d)    (7.8)    (l  +  i)-5.  80   (7.8) 

(1  +  i) 
L,  =  49.934  (7.8)  (1 +  i)  f  182.1  -  (71. 86-71. 86d)  (7.8)  (1  +  i) 


(1) 


(4) 
(5) 
(6) 

(7) 

(8) 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Factoring: 

(9)  Li  =  7.8  (1  +  i)  [49.934- (71. 86-71.86d)J+ 182.1 

Simplifying: 

(10)  L,  =  7.8  (1  +  i)  (49.934) -71.86  +  71.86d)  + 182.1 
Li  =  7.8  (1  +  i)  (71.86d-21.926)  + 182.1 

Substituting  (6)  and  (10)  in  (1): 
(11;  X  =  7.8(l  +  i)  (71.86d-21.926)  +  182.1-11.077 

Simplifying: 

(12)  X=(l  +  i)  (560.508d- 171.023) +  171.023 

(13)  X  =  560.508d-l71.023  +  560.508di- 171. 023i+ 171.023 

(14)  X  =  560.508d  +  560.508di-171.023i 

(15)  X  =  560.508d  +  i  (560.508d- 171.023) 

Additional  Loss  if  Elasticity  of  Demand  for  Steel  is  as  High  as  1: 
If  the  elasticity  =  1: 

(16)  ''="i4d  ^^®^  Appendix  II) 

Substituting  (16)  and  (15): 

(17)  X  =  560.508d+j4d(560.508d- 171.023) 

Simplifying: 
-^^560.508d-560.508d^  +  560.508d^- 171.023d 


14077 


(18) 
(19) 
(20) 


1-d 


._560.508d- 171.023d 

^389.485d 
1-d 

Substituting  various  values  for  d: 


d 

X 

d 

X 

d 

X 

d 

X 

0.1 

3  9 
7.9 
12.0 
16.2 
20.5 

24.9 
29.3 
33.9 
38.5 
43.3 

48.1 
53.1 
58.2 
63.4 
68.7 

74.2 

.02 

.07    

.12 

.17 

79.8 

.03—. 

.08 

.13 

.18 

85.5 

.04 __. 

.09 

.10 _... 

.14... 

.15 

.19 

r. 

.05 

.20 

Additional  Loss  if  Prices  Had  Been  Reduced  and  No  Increase  in  Volume  Resulted: 
If  no  increase  in  volume  resulted: 

(21)  i=:0 

Substituting  (21)  in  (15)  the* general  equation: 

(22)  X  =  560.508d 

Substituting  various  values  for  d: 


d 

\^ 

d 

X 

d 

X 

d 

X 

0.01 

5.6 
1112 
16.8 
22.4 
28.0 

0.16 

33.6 
39.2 
44.8 
50.4 
56.1 

61.7 
67.3 
72.9 
78.5 
84.1 

0.16-. 

■g9.7 

.02. 

.07 

.12 

13 

.17. __ 

18 

95.3 

.03 

08 

100.9 

.04 

.09 

.14 

19 

106.5 

.05 

.10 - 

.15 

20 

112.1 

Appendix  IV.  Weighted  Tonnage  Which  Must  Be  Shipped  to  Break  Even 

AT  Various  Price  Levels 
Given: 

Costs  =  55.734  V+ 182.1,  where: 

Costs  are  in  millions  of  dollars,  and 
V  =  millions  of  weighted  tons  shipped 

Transportation  and  Miscellaneous  Revenues  under  1938  conditions  = 
5.80  V 

Let:   P  =  Sales  per  weighted  ton  shipped 
V|  =  V  at  the  break-even  point 

At  the  break-even  point  Sales  and  Revenues  will  equal  costs;  therefore: 
P  V,+ 5.80  V,  =  55.734  V,  + 182.1 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


•55.734  V,  =  182.1 


14Q78 

Transposing: 

P  V,  +  5.80  V,- 

Factoring  and  simplifying: 
Vi  (P-49.934)  =  182.1 

Dividing  by  (P-49.934): 
v_      182.1 
^'     P-49.934 
Substituting  various  values  for  P: 


Price  conditions 

P 

(P-49.934) 

V, 

Average  1038 

71.86 
67.33 
64.67 
60.60 

2).  926 
17.  396 
14.  736 
10.666 

8  305 

2d  half  1938 

10  468 

Average  1938  less  10% 

12  357 

2d  half  1938  less  10% 

17  073 

Appendix  V.  Computation  of  Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Offset 
Decreases  in  Price 

Given: 

Total  costs^  182.1  millions  of  dollars +$55. 734  per  weighted  ton. 

Sales,  average  1938  prices =$71.86  per  weighted  ton  shipped. 

Sales,  2d  half  1938  prices  =  $67. 33    " 
Transportation   and  miscella- 
neous revenues  ■=   $5.80    "  "  "  " 

Let: 

V  =  volume  before  price  decrease,  in  weighted  tons. 

¥!•=  volume,  in  weighted  tons,  needed  to  offset  decrease  in  price. 

S  =  sales,   exclusive  of  other  revenues,  per  weighted  ton  shipped   before 

decrease  in  price, 
d  ■=  fractional  decrease  in  price. 
X  =  fractional  increase  in  volume  needed  to  offset  d. 


(1) 

(2) 
(3) 


(4) 


(5) 


(6) 


(7) 


(8) 


Then: 


=  SV+5.80  V- (182.1  +  55.734  V) 


V,- 55.734  V, 


_Vi-V_Vi     V_   Vi 
X-     V     ~V     V~V      ^ 

Profit  or  loss  before  price  decrease 

Profit  or  loss  after  price  decrease=(S-dS)  Vi  +  5.80  V,- 182. 1  +  55.734  V, 
If  the  increase  in  Vi  over  B  is  to  offset  the  decrease  in  S,  (2)  and  (3) 
will  be  equal.     Hence: 

SV+5.80  V- 182.1-55.734  V=(S-dS)  V,  +  5.80  V,- 182.1-55.734  V 

Adding  182.1  to  both  sides: 

SV+5.80  V- 55.734  V=(S-dS)  Vi  +  5 

Factoring  and  simplifying: 

V  (S-49.934)  =  V,  [(S-dS) -49.934] 
Removing  brackets: 

V  (S- 49.934)  =Vi  (S-dS- 49.934) 
Vi^     S- 49.934 

V  S-dS-49.934 
Substituting  in  (1) : . 

S-49.934 
^     S-dS-49.934     ^ 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14079 


Substituting  percentage  decreases  from  the  average  1938  prices. 


21.926 


At  average  1938  prices: 

71.86-49.934 

"71.86-71. 86d-49.934     ^"^  21.926- 71.86d     ^ 
Substituting  various  values  for  d: 


d 

21.926-71.86d 

21.926 

,           21.926           ,. 

21.926-71 .86d 

''^    21.926-71.86d     " 

0  01                                                             

21. 207 
20. 489 
19. 770 
19.052 
18.333 
17.614 

li  177 
15.459 
14.  740 
14.021 
13. 303 
12.584 

ll!l47 
10.428 
9.710 
8.991 
8.273 
7.554 
6.835 
6.117 
5.398 
4.680 
3.961 
3.242 
2.524 
1.805 
1.087 
0.368 

1.0339 
1.0701 
1.1091 
1. 1509 
1.1960 

1.  2448 
1.2977 
1.3554 
1.4183 
1.4875 
1.5638 
1.64S2 
1.7424 
1.S47S 
1.9670 
2. 1026 

2.  2581 
2.4387 
2.6503 
2. 9026 
3.2079 

3.  5844 
4.0619 
4. 0850 

5.  5355 

6.  7631 
8.6870 

12. 1474 
20.1711 
59. 5815 

.0339 

.02                                                      

.0701 

.1091 

.1500 

.1960 

.2448 

.07 

.3977 

08 

.3554 

09 

.4183 

10                                                         

.4875 

.11 

.5638 

.6482 

.7424 

.8478 

.9670 

16 

1.1026 

17 

1,2581 

18                                                     .... 

1.4387 

19                                                         

1.6503 

1.9026 

2.2079 

2.6844 

3. 0619 

24 

3. 6850 

25 

4. 6355 

.26 .. 

27                                                    .     

5.7631 
7.6870 

28                                               

11.1474 

19.1711 

59. 5815 

Substituting  percentage  decreases  from 
At  2d  half,  1938,  prices: 
67.33-49.934 


"~67.33-67.33d-49.934 
Substituting  various  values  for  d : 


1  = 


half,  19S8,  prices: 


17.396 


17.396-67.33d 


d 

17.396 -67.33d 

17.396 

17.396 

17.396-67.33d 

^^■l7.396-67.33d    " 

16.723 
16.049 
15.376 
14.  703 
14.030 
13.356 
12.683 
12.010 
11.336 
10.663 
9.990 
9.316 
8.643 
7.970 
7.297 
6.623 
5.950 
5.277 
4.603 
3.930 
3.257 

lioio 

1.237 
0.564 

1.040 
1.084 
1.131 
1.183 
1.240 
1.302 
1.372 
1.448 
1.635 
1.631 
1.741 
1.867 
2.013 
2.183 
2.384 
2.627 
2.924 
3.297 
3.779 
4.426 
5.341 
6.735 
9.108 
14.063 
30. 844 

.040 

.084 

.03 

04 

.18S 

05                                                                       .  .. 

240 

.06                                                       

.302 

.372 

.448 

09 

.635 

10 

.631 

.741 

.867 

1.018 

1.183 

1.384 

1.627 

1.024 

.18 

.19... 

.20 - 1 

2.297 
2.779 
3.426 

22 mil  I"I 

4.341 

5.735 

.23             ...                 

8.108 

13.063 

.26 

29.844 

14080        CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Appendix  VI.  Operating  Rate  Required  To  Earn  5%  on  Tangible  Invest- 
ment IF  Break-Even  Point  at  Over  90%  of  Capacity 

Tangible  Investment:  «^«"-  -?.  l^^^  Dec.  31,  19S8 

Assets $1,918,729,289     $1,711,279,006 

Less:  Current  Liabilities 117,331,071  79,261,329 

Total  Investment $1,801,398,218     $1,632,017,677 

(Bondholders'  &  Stockholders'  Interests) 

Less  Intangibles 260,368,522  1 

Tangible  Investment $1,  541,  029,  696     $1,  632,  017,  676 


Average  Tangible  Investment,  1938 $1,586,523,686 

5%  Return  on  Average  Tangible  Investment $79,  326,  184 

Less:  Bond  Interest 8,262,327 


Return  after  Bond  Interest $71,063,857 


The  break-even  point  would  be  at  over  90%  of  capacity  if  prices  were  10% 
lower  than  the  average  prices  prevailing  in  the  2d  half  of  1938  (see  Appendix  IV). 
At  these  prices  total  sales  and  revenues  would  amount  to  $66.40  per  weighted  ton 
of  tonnage  products  shipped. 

At  these  prices,  profits,  before  income  taxes,  in  millions  of  dollars  =66.40  — 
182.1-55.734  V.      (See  Appendix  IV.) 

To  realize  71.0  million  dollars,  ignoring  income  taxes: 

71.0=66.40  V-182.1-55.734  V 
10.666  V  =  253.1 
253  1 
V  =  YK-?^  =  23.73  millions  of  weighted  tons 

The  trend  of  the  relationship  between  tons  of  rolled  and  finished  products 
shipped  and  weighted  tons  of  all  tonnage  products  shipped  indicates  that  the 
weighted  capacity  figure  for  all  tonnage  products  equivalent  to  the  17.9  millions 
of  unweighted  tons  constituting  the  rolled  and  finished  capacity  as  of  January  1, 
1939,  would  be  17.85  millions  of  weighted  tons.     Hence,  at  such  prices  operations 

23  73 
would  have  to  reach  the  impossible  rate  of  yfs^R'  or  133%  of  capacity,  to  realize 

a  return  as  modest  as  5%  on  tangible  investment. 

Appendix  VII.  Effect  of  Inter  Company  Transactions  on  Profit 
AND  Loss  Statement 

The  consolidated  profit  and  loss  statements  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation, 
submitted  to  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  do  not  state  the  sales  and  revenues 
and  the  cost  of  goods  sold  and  operating  expenses  of  transportation  and  miscel- 
laneous operations  on  a  purely  integrated  basis.  This  is  to  say  that  the  sales 
shown  are  not  merely  sales  to  purchasers  other  than  subsidiaries  of  the  Corpora- 
tion, but  include  sales  between  subsidiary  companies.  Thus  tlie  sale  for  $80  of  a 
product  costing  $60  to  another  subsidiary  which  resold  it  to  outside  purchasers  for 
$100  would  result  in  sales  of  $180  on  the  profit  and  loss  statement.  Cost  of  goods 
sold  would  similarl}'  involve  a  duplication  and  would  amount  in  all  to  $60,  the  cost 
to  the  first  company,  plus  $80,  the  cost  to  the  second  company,  or  $140.  This 
would  leave  a  gross  profit  of  $40.  Considering  the  consolidated  companies  as  a 
single  unit,  what  Has  really  happened  is  that  goods  costing  $60  were  sold  for  $100, 
leaving  a  profit  oi  $40.  thus  the  profit  is  neither  overstated  nor  underslatcd  by 
this  method  of  handling.  From  an  integrated  viewpoint,  both  sales  and  costs 
are  inflated,  however,  by  the  amount  of  the  inter-company  .sales. 

This  relationship  is  not  disturoed  by  sales  to  suhsid-.iries  for  use  in  constructing 
capital  equipment  since  such  sales  arc  treated  as  outside  sales  and  the  full  sales 
price  is  charged  to  capital  recount  by  the  purchasing  company  and  on  the  con- 
solidated balance  sheet  of  the  Corporation.  Only  goods  sold  for  conversion  or 
resale  are  treated  as  inter-company  items. 

The  fact  that  goods  purchased  by  one  subsidiary  from  another  are  retained  in 
inventory  or  that  goods  sold  were  sold  from  inventory  does  not  affect  the  relation- 
ship between  inter-company  sales  and  integrated  costs,  since  adjustment  is  always 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14081 

made  to  defer  the  taking  up  as  profit  on  the  consolidated  profit  and  loss  statement 
the  profit  shown  by  one  subsidiary  on  sales  to  another  subsidiary  when  the  goods 
sold  are  still  in  the  inventory  of  the  second  subsidiary.  This  profit  is  taken  up 
as  realized  profit  only  when  the  goods  are  sold  outside  the  organization.  The 
eff'ect  of  this  adjustment  for  inter-company  profit  in  inventory  may  be  seen  in  the 
following  series  of  illustrations. 

Case  I.  Company  A  sells  to  afl^liated  Company  B  for  $100  a  product  which 
cost  it  $80.  Company  B  sells  this  product  for  $120.  The  sales  and  cost  of  goods 
sold  set-up  would  be  as  follows: 


Item 

Co.  A 

Co.  B 

Consoli- 
dated 

Inter-Co. 
Sales 

Integrated 
Basis 

Sales 

$100 
80 

$120 
100 

20 

$220 
180 

$100 
100 

$120 

Cost  of  goods  sold 

80 

20 

40 

Case  II.  In  addition  to  the  transaction  in  Case  I,  Company  A  sells  to  Company 
B  for  $80  a  product  which  cost  it  $60.  Company  B  has  this  in  inventory  at  the 
end  of  the  year,  and  the  profit  shown  by  Company  A  on  the  second  sale  to  Com- 
pany B  is  treated  as  unrealized  on  the  consolidated  profit  and  loss  statement 
because  the  product  has  not  been  sold  outside  the  consolidated  organization.  The 
sales  and  cost  of  goods  sold  set-up  would  then  be  as  follows: 


Item 

Co.  A 

Co.  B 

Inter-Co. 
Profits  in 
Inventory 

Consoli- 
dated 

Inter-Co. 

Sales 

Inte- 
grated 
Basis 

Sales 

$180 

$120 

$300 

$180 

$120 

Cost  of  goods  manufactured  or  pur- 

$140 

$180 
80 

$320 
60 

$180 

$140 

$20 

6(1 

Cost  of  goods  sold 

140 

100 

■      20 

260 

180 

80 

40 

20 

20 

-  40 

Case  III.  In  addition  to  the  transactions  in  Cases  I  and  II,  Company  B  sells 
for  $75  a  product  which  it  bought  from  Company  A  the  previous  year  for  $65. 
It  had  cost  Company  B  $60  to  produce  this  article,  with  the  result  that  $5  inter- 
company profits  tied  up  in  inventory  was  deducted  from  consolidated  gross 
profits  in  the  previous  year  by  addition  to  cost  of  goods  sold  in  a  manner  similar 
to  the  $20  adjustment  for  inter-company  profit  in  inventory  in  Case  II.  The  sales 
and  cost  ol  goods  sold  would  then  be  as  follows: 


Item 

Co.  A 

Co.  B 

Inter-Co. 
Profits  in 
Inventory 

Consoli- 
dated 

Inter-Co. 
Sales 

Inte- 
grated 
Basis 

Sales 

$180 

$195 

$375 

$180 

$193 

65 
180 

$5 

60 

320 

380 
60 

60 

Cost  of  goods  manufactured  or  pur- 

140 

180 
180 

140 

Total  goods  available  for  sale... 

140 

245 
80 

5 
20 

200 
60 

140 

165 

15 

320 

180 

140 

40 

30 

15 

55 

;5 

The  fact  that  goods  purchased  from  another  subsidiary  are  usually  further  fabri- 
cated before  being  resold  does  not  change  the  relationship.  It  merely  adds  the 
cost  of  such  fabrication  to  the  cost  of  goods  sold  bv  the  purchasing  subsidiary. 


14082 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


rience  the  integrated  cost  will  be  the  cost  to  the  first  subsidiary  plus  the  cost  of 
fabrication  incurred  by  the  second  subsidiary.  It  will  still  be  less  than  the  cost 
shown  on  the  consolidated  profit  and  loss  statement  by  the  amount  of  the  inter- 
company sales. 

This  may  be  illustrated  by  a  situation  where  the  first  subsidiary  sells  a  product 
costing  $60  to  the  second  subsidiary  for  $80.  The  second  subsidiary  fabricates 
it  further  at  a  cost  of  $10  and  sells  it  to  an  outside  purchaser  for  $120.  The  profit 
and  loss  set-up  is  shown  below,  the  column  headed  "Consolidated",  showing  the 
figures  that  would  appear  on  the  consolidated  profit  ."nd  loss  statement  and  the 
column  headed  "Integrated"  showing  the  figures  on  an  integrated  basis: 


Item 

Co.  A 

Co.B 

Consoli- 
dated 

Inter-Co. 
Sales 

Integrated 
Basis 

Sales -- 

$80 

$120 

$200 

$80 

$120 

Cost  of  goods  purchased 

80 
10 

80 
70 

80 

60 
60 

70 

90 

150 

80 

70 

Gross  Profit 

20 

30 

50 

SO 

It  should  be  noted  that  the  costs  shown  on  the  consolidated  profit  and  loss 
statements  are  always  in  excess  of  integrated  cost  by  the  amount  of  the  current 
year's  inter-company  sales.  Hence  it  is  proper  to  deduct  from  costs  of  goods  sold 
as  shown  on  the  profit  and  loss  statement  the  amount  ot  the  inter-company  sales 
and  revenues  in  order  to  arrive  at  a  cost  figure  which  is  comparable  with  the 
tonnages  shipped  to  outside  purchasers. 


Exhibit  No.  1417 

AN  ANALYSIS  OF  STEEL  PRICES,  VOLUME  AND  COSTS  CONTROL- 
LING LIMITATIONS  ON  PRICE  REDUCTIONS 

This  analysis  was  prepared  by  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  in  connec- 
ton  with  its  studies  in  preparation  for  the  hearings  on  the  steel  industry  before 
the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee.  The  work  was  under  the  super- 
vision of  Theodoie  O.  Yntema,  Professor  of  Statistics,  UnivQrsii)y  of  Chicago. 

OCTOBEB  30,  1939. 


Importance  of  Peice-Volume-Cost  Relationship 

The  success  of  mass  production  methods  in  American  industrial  practice  has 
given  much  emphasis  to  the  importance  of  volume  in  reducing  costs.  Failure  to 
appreciate,  in  the  case  of  the  steel  industry,  the  limitations  of  the  extent  to  which 
increased  volume  means  reduced  costs  per  unit  of  product  has  frequently  been 
made  the  basis  of  the  charge  that  steel  prices  are  higher  than  thq|>y  should  be  arid 
that  the  absence  of  price  competition,  rather  than  the  limitations  imposed  by 
costs,  is  the  reason  why  steel  prices  are  not  lower  than  they  are.  It  is  further 
said  that  if  steel  prices  were  lowered  in  times  of  recession  more  steel  would  be  sold 
and  payrolls  and  employment  would  be  better  maintained.  The  fact  of  the  matter 
is  that  steel  prices  are  not  high.  In  recent  years  they  have  barely  covered  costs. 
In  the  last  ten  years,  1929  to  1938,  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  realized 
a  return  of  only  1.9%  on  the  combined  investment  of  the  bondholders  and  stock- 
holders.    From  1930  to  1938  its  rate  of  return  has  averaged  less  than  1%. 

However,  the  contention  that  steel  prices  are  too  high  is  not  made  in  ignorance 
of  the  small  margin  of  profit  currently  being  realized.  The  theory  of  those  who 
would  lower  steel  prices  is  that  such  reductions  would  greatly  stimulate  sales  and 
that  volume  and  costs  are  so  interrelated  in  the  production  of  steel  that  the  cost 
per  ton  would  be  drastically  reduced  if  volume  were  increased.  Hence,  it  is 
argued  that  if  prices  were  decreased  even  belc^v  present  costs,  volume  would  be 
stimulated  to  a  point  where  costs  would  drop  suflSciently  to  make  steel  production 
profitable  at  the  reduced  prices.  In  determining  whether  or  not  this  is  so,  two 
all  important  factors  must  be  considered.  They  are  (1)  the  amount  by  which 
unit  costs  do  in  fact  shrink  as  volume  increases  and  (2)  the  amount  by  which 
volume  is  in  fact  increased  by  lowering  prices. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14083 

Costs  and  Volume 

It  would  have  been  possible  to  obtain  some  idea  of  the  way  in  which  the  total 
costs  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  increase  with 
increases  in  output  simply  by  comparing  total  costs  shown  on  its  consolidated 
annual  profit  and  loss  statements  over  a  period  of  years  with  the  tonnage  of  rolled 
and  finished  products  shipped  each  year.  Such  an  analysis  would  not  be  wholly 
accurate,  however,  for  several  reasons. 

In  the  first  place,  the  total  costs  for  the  same  number  of  tons  shipped  would 
differ  depending  upon  the  type  of  product  whose  tonnage  predominated.  For 
instance,  if  the  shipment  figures  showed  that  in  each  of  two  years  10,000,000  tons 
had  been  produced,  the  costs  would  naturally  be  higher  in  the  year  in  which  high 
cost  products,  such  as  sheets  and  tin  plate,  constituted  the  larger  portion  of  the 
tonnage,  than  in  a  year  when  lower  cost  items,  such  as  rails  and  heavy  plates, 
predominated.  In  the  following  analysis  this  difficulty  has  been  adjusted  for  by 
computing  for  each  year  a  tonnage  figure  representing  what  the  equivalent  gross 
tonnage,  from  a  cost  standpoint,  would  have  been  if  the  total  shipments  were 
constituted  of  normal  proportions  of  high  and  low  cost  products.  Similarly,  the 
total  tonnage  of  rolled  and  finished  products  shipped  has  been  adjusted  to  include 
the  equivalent  gross  tons  of  steel  represented  by  the  products  other  than  steel 
which  are  sold  on  a  tonnage  basis  by  the  Corporation's  subsidiaries. 

Secondly,  the  cost  figures  taken  from  the  profit  and  loss  statements  represent 
costs  in  different  years  when  different  wage  rates,  interest  rates,  tax  rates  and 
prices  prevailed.  Hence,  it  is  necessary  to  adjust  the  cost  figures  for  years  prior 
to  1938  to  conditions  prevailing  in  1938  in  order  to  ascertain  what  the  relation 
between  costs  and  volume  would  be  as  of  1938,  the  most  recent  full  year  and  the 
one  in  which  material  prices,  pension  payments,  and  wage,  interest,  and  tax  rates 
are  most  representative  of  present-day  conditions. 

Since  diffarent  adjustments  are  necessarily  required  for  different  types  of  costs, 
the  total  costs  of  the  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries,  exclusive  of  inter-company 
items  and  costs  connected  with  extraneous  non-operating  transactions,  for  each 
of  the  years  1927  to  1938  were  broken  down  into  (1)  interest,  (2)  pensions,  (3) 
depreciation  and  depletion,  (4)  taxes  other  than  social  security  and  Federal  income 
and  profits  taxes,  (5)  payroll,  (6)  social  security  taxes,  and  (7)  other  expenses. 
Each  of  these  costs  as  they  appeared  in  past  years  has  been  separately  adjusted 
to  the  levels  of  1938. ^  Federal  income  taxes  have  been  omitted  from  the  com- 
putations because  they  depend  upon  profits  rather  than  volume  and  it  was  the 
purpose  of  this  analysis  to  work  out  a  cost-volume  relationship  which  can  be 
compared  to  total  sales  and  revenues  at  various  price  and  volume  levels. 

The  total  costs  obtained  by  adding  together  the  adjusted  items  for  each  year 
represented  what  the  costs  would  have  been  in  those  years  if  1938  prices  and 
interest,  wage,  and  tax  rates  had  prevailed.  A  further  adjustment  was  then  made, 
based  on  the  downward  trend  of  costs  in  relation  to  volume  over  the  period  of 
time  involved,  to  take  into  consideration  the  extent  to  which  the  same  tonnages 
could  have  been  produced  in  1938,  because  of  increased  eflficiency,  at  lower  cost 
than  they  could  have  been  produced  in  prior  years  at  1938  prices,  pensions  and 
wage,  interest,  and  tax  rates. 

'  The  adjustments  applied  to  each  of  the  cost  factors  enumerated  were  as  follows: 

fl)  Interest— The  interest  eost,  not  being  dependent  on  volume,  was  converted  to  1938  conditions  by 
substituting  the  1938  interest  charge  in  the  figures  for  each  year. 

(2)  Pensions— The  cost  of  pensions,  like  interest,  was  converted  to  1938  conditions  by  substituting  the 
1938  figure. 

(3)  Depreciation  and  Depletion— Since  there  has  been  no  important  change  in  the  Corporation's  account- 
ing policy,  no  adjustment  has  been  made  in  the  depreciation  and  depletion  figures. 

(4)  Taxes  Other  than  Federal  Income  and  Profits  Taxes  and  Social  Security  Taxes— Since  analysis  of  the 
relation  of  taxes  to  volume  discloses  that  the  taxes  for  1933  onward  follow  one  pattern  while  the  taxes  for 
previous  years  were  considerably  lower,  adjustment  was  made  for  the  changed  tax  laws  by  substituting  in 
prior  years  the  taxes  for  the  volume  involved  which  were  indicated  by  the  1932-1938  line  of  average  relation- 
ship between  taxes  and  volume. 

(5)  Payroll— The  payrolls  for  each  of  the  respective  years  were  adjusted  to  1938  rates  on  the  basis  of  the 
proportionate  change  in  the  average  hourly  earnings  between  the  year  in  which  the  payroll  was  incurred 
and  1938. 

(6)  Social  Security  Taxes— Social  security  taxes  at  1938  rates  for  the  various  amounts  of  payroll  were 
estimated  by  applying  the  1938  ratio  of  the?e  taxes  to  payroll. 

(7)  Other  Expenses— This  item  consists  largely  of  goods  and  services  purchased  from  others.  An  approxi- 
mate adjustment  for  the  changing  prices  of  these  items  which  the  Corporation  must  purchase  has  been 
made  on  the  basis  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  statistics  index  of  wholesale  prices  for  commoditiesother  than 
food  and  farm  products.  While  low  operating  rates  are  usually  accompanied  by  somewhat  lower  material 
prices,  material  costs  were  adjusted  to  1938  price  levels  in  this  study  in  order  to  ascertain  the  chan?"'  'n 
unit  costs  which  would  be  attributable  to  changes  in  volume  alone. 


14084        OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

The  final  adjusted  costs  and  the  weighted  tonnages  to  which  they  are  related 
are  as  follows: 

Table   1. —  Total  Costs  and  Volume  of  Business — 1938  Conditions  ' — United  States 
Steel  Corporation  and  All  Subsidiaries 


Millions   of   Weighted 
Tons    of    Products 
Shipped 

Costs— 1938 

Conditions 

(Millions  of 

Dollars) 

Year  on 
which  Esti- 
mate is 
Based 

Millions   of   Weighted 
Tons    of    Products 
Shipped 

Costs-1938 

Conditions 

(Millions  of 

Dollars; 

Year  on 
which  Esti- 
mate is 
Based 

436.0 
510.0 
512.0 
610.3 
614.3 
628.9 

1932 
1934 
1933 
1935 
1938 
1931 

818.2 

954.5 
916.2 
966.2 
979.0 

1936 

6.1 

11.9.  -                      

1930 

13.0    

1927 

7.6 

13.2 

1937 

7.8 

1928 

8.1 

15.1 

1929 

!  Total  costs  are  adjusted  to  1938. interest,  pension,  wage,  and  tax  rates,  to  :938  price  level,  and  to  1938 
efficiency. 

These  costs  have  been  plotted  in  relation  to  the  volume  of  shipments  on  Chart 
1.  Insertion  of  the  straight  line  established  by  the  respective  points  shows  the 
average  relationship  between  volume  and  cost  under  1938  conditions.  The 
smallness  of  the  vertical  deviations  of  the  various  points  from  this  line  of  aver- 
age relationship  indicates  how  closely  the  costs  of  the  United  States  Steel  Cor- 
poration and  its  subsidiaries  follow  this  pattern. 

Chart  1 


RELATIONSHIP  BETWEEN  TOTAL  COSTS  OF  OPERATION 
AND  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS  -  1938  CONDITIONS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

1200 
HOC 
1000 
900     % 
800     1 
700     ^ 
600     o 
500     ^ 
Ann     ° 

1100 

1000 

^     900 

i "° 

°     700 
o    600 
^     500 
2     400 

i     300 

200 

100 

0 

^ 

1927 

^ 

iis 

^ 

1930 

^ 

J 

35.- 

r<^. 

1934 

^.. 

-. 

^ 

^ 

^ 

300     g 
200 
100 
0 

_^ 

^ 

( 

NOTE:  TOTAL  CO- 

)      1      2      3     4      5     6      7     8     9     10    11    12    13    14    15    16    17    1 

MILLIONS  CF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL  TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 

STS  ADJUSTtO  TO  193S  IMTERtST,  T«.  PWSBN.  AND  WASE  RATES;  TO  1938  PRICE  IfVELS  AND  TO  l?38  EFTCiENCY 

8 

Mathematical  computation  of  the  cost  relationship  indicated  by  the  cost  line 
shows  that  the  total  costs  of  the  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  amount  to 
$55.73  per  weighted  ton,^  plus  $182,100,000.'     The  $182,100,000  represents  the 

'  The  total  weighted  tonnage  shipped  does  not  include  the  volume  of  goods  and  services  sold  on  other 
than  a  tonnage  basis.  This  additional  cost  of  $55.73  represents  the  additionrtl  cost  of  all  goods  and  services 
shipped  or  sold  per  weighted  ton  of  tonnage  products  shipped. 

'  A  similar  analysis  of  the  unadjusted  costs  shows  that  the  average  relationship  prevailing  during  the 
period  1927-1938  between  costs  and  volume  was  such  that  total  costs  tended  to  be  $.'>4.5I  per  weighted  ton 
plus  $120,530,000.  If  these  figures  were  substituted  for  those  based  on  the  adjusted  costs,  the  calculations 
which  are  to  follow  would  be  changed  considerably,  but  the  general  conclusions  as  to  the  increase  in  volume 
needed  (o  oflset  a  price  decrease  would  remain  unaffected. 


OONOENTRAXr.  X  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14085 

portion  of  the  costs  which  remains  the  same,  regardless  of  the  vokime  of  steel 
produced,  as  long  as  the  Corporation's  subsidiaries  are  operating  at  all.  Such 
costs  are  frequently  termed  ""xed  costs"  or  "overhead  costs."  The  $55.73  per 
weighted  ton  represents  the  a  iditional  cost  of  the  increased  operations  incidental 
to  each  successive  weighted  ton  of  product  sliipped.  Such  costs  are  termed 
"variable  costs,"  "incremental  costs,"  or  "additional  costs."  In  the  case  of  the 
Corporation  these  additional  costs  remain  constant  at  $55.73  per  ton  through 
the  range  of  volume  within  which  the  Corporation's  suljsidiaries  operated  from 
1927  to  1938.  While  additional  costs  might  possibly  vary  if  facilities  were 
pressed  to  the  absolute  limit,  or  if  operations  fell  to  a  point  even  lower  than  they 
did  in  the  depth  of  the  depression  in  1932,  the  1927-1938  experience  includes 
annual  rates  of  operation  varying  from  17.7%  to  90.4%  of  ingot  capacity. 

Although  the  ij:<  rease  in  costs  with  each  additional  ton  of  steel  produced  tends 
to  remain  constant,  this  does  not  mean  that  the  average  cost  per  ton  of  steel 
remains  the  same.  Since  the  average  cost  amounts  to  $55.73  per  ton  plus  the 
pro  rata  portion  of  fixed  costs  and  since  the  $182,100,000  of  fixed  costs  can  be 
distributed  over  more  units  as  production  is  increased,  the  average  cost  of 
operations  per  ton  of  steel  shipped  will  obviously  decrease  as  volume  rises. 

It  should  be  noted  here,  however,  that  while  the  costs  mentioned  are  exclusive 
of  all  non-operating  income  and  expense,  they  cover  all  operations  of  the  United 
States  Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  and,  hence,  do  not  represent  merely 
the  cost  of  producing  steel.  Furthermore,  even  weighted  tonnages  shipped  do 
not  reflect  the  full  volume  of  business,  since  some  goods  and  services  are  sold  by 
the  Corporation's  subsidiaries  which  are  not  measured  in  tons.  Nevertheless, 
other  operations  rise  and  fall  with  increases  and  decreases  in  shipments  of  prod- 
ucts to  a  sufficient  extent  that  the  total  costs  maintain  approximately  the 
relationship  to  shipments  just  described. 

An  analysis  of  the  elements  composing  the  fixed  and  the  additional  costs 
discloses  that  they  are  composed  as  follows: 

Table  2. — Elements  of  Total  Costs  19S8  Conditions — United  States  Steel  Corpora- 
tion and  all  Subsidiaries 


Item 

Costs  that 
must  be  met 

regardle5s 

of  operating 

rate 

Additiona. 
cost  lor  each 

additional 
weighted  ton 

of  product 
shipped 

$8,  300,  000 
7,  700,  000 

24,  200,  OOO 

62,  100,  000 
2,  500,  000 

47,  800,  000 

0.00 

1.43 

Payroll 

29  10 

Social  Security  Taxes 

1  16 

Other  Cash  E.xpenses 

21.67 

$152,  600,  000 
29,  500,  000 

2:37 

Total  Costs 

$182,100,000 

$55  73 

The  relationship  of  the  various  elements  of  cost  to  volume  is  graphically  portrayed 
in  Chart  2.  It  is  worthy  of  note  that  not  only  does  payroll  constitute  the  largest 
item  of  additional  costs  but  it  is  also  the  largest  element  of  the  overhead  or  fixed 
costs,  amounting  to  over  one-third  of  that  item. 

Prices  and  Volume 

If  the  relationship  between  volume  and  costs  is  known,  it  becomes  possible  to 
determine  the  increase  in  volume  that  would  be  needed  as  the  result  of  a  price 
reduction  in  order  to  ofiFset  the  decreased  amount  received  for  each  unit  of  product 
sold,  assuming  no  reduction  in  wage  rates,  material  prices,  and  other  such  factors. 
Similarly,  to  the  extent  that  it  is  possible  to  estimate  the  increase  in  volume  that 
would  be  likely  to  result  from  a  price  decrease,  it  is  possible  to'estimate  what  is  to 
be  gained  or  lost  by  reducing  prices. 

In  connection  with  the  increase  in  volume  that  would  be  attained  through  a 
price  reduction,  it  must  be  remembered  that  if  any  substantial  increase  results,  it 
will  have  to  result  from  an  increase  in  the  total  amount  of  steel  consumed,  since 
competitive  meeting  of  prices  will  generally  prevent  any  sustained  increase  in  the 


14086  OON01]NTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

participation  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  in  the 
going  volume  of  business.  On  the  other  hand,  the  rise  to  be  expected  in  the  total 
volume  of  steel  consumed  as  a  result  of  a  drop  in  prices  is  not  very  great  in  the 
steel  industry.  Steel  is  not  sold  directly  to  the  ultimate  consumer.  'It  reaches 
him  only  as  a  part  of  the  finished  automobile,  typewriter,  apartment  house,  tin 
can,  or  safety  pin,  as  the  case  may  be.  In  other  cases,  steel  is  used  only  as  part 
of  the  machinery  and  equipment  used  in  making  the  products  which  reach  the 
man  in  the  street.  No  matter  how  low  the  price,  steel  can  be  sold  only  if  products 
which  are  produced  from  steel  or  by  the  use  of  steel  are  being  sold.  In  the  case  of 
products  produced  from  steel,  the  cost  of  steel  is  usually  so  small  a  fraction  of  the 

Chart  2 


COMPOSITION  OF  TOTAL  COSTS  OF  OPERATION 
IN  RELATION  TO  VOLUME  OF  BUSINESS 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
1200 


1100 


NOTE.    19271938  EXPERIENCE  ADJUSTED  TO  1938  CONDITIONS 


total  cost  of  the  product  that  a  reduction  in  steel  prices,  even  if  passed  on  to  the 
ultimate  consumer,  would  not  result  in  a  sufficient  decrease  in  the  price  of  the 
finished  product  to  cause  an  appreciable  increase  in  its  sale.  As  far  as  steel  for 
production  is  concerned,  it  is  evident  that  regardless  of  the  price  of  steel  no  one 
will  invest  in  productive  machinery  unless  he  feels  the  prospects  in  his  particular 
line  of  business  justify  such  investment. 

Analysis  of  the  influence  of  price  as  a  factor  affecting  slefiT  consumption  in  the 
automobile,  railroad  and  container  industries  reveals  that  a  decrease  in  the  price 
of  steel  can  increase  the  consumption  of  steel  only  to  a  limited  extent  by  promoting 
the  use  of  more  steel  per  unit  or  permitting  stool  to  be  substituted  for  some 
other  competing  rnaterial.  Any  substantial  increase  in  the  consumption  of  steel 
in  these  industries  could  be  brought  about  only  by  increasing  the  consumption  of 
the  ^nished  product  or  service  rendered.     Consequently,  the  price  elasticity  of  the 


I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       14087 

demand  for  steel  depends  primarily  upon  the  price  elasticity  of  demand  for  the 
finished  product  and  the  relative  cost  of  steel  to  the  price  of  the  finished  product. 

The  elasticity  of  demand  is  measured  by  the  ratio  of  the  relative  resulting 
increase  in  volume  to  the  relative  decrease  in  price.  For  example,  in  the  case  of 
automobiles,  an  exhaustive  study  by  Messrs.  Roos  and  von  Szeliski  ♦  showed  that 
the  price  elasticity  of  demand  for  automobiles  was  about  1.5,  which  means  that  a 
1%  reduction  in  price  would  increase  the  number  of  automobiles  sold  about  1.5%. 
Since  the  cost  of  steel  in  the  form  sold  by  the  steel  producer  is  about  one-tenth  of 
the  retail  price  of  a  representative  low-priced  automobile,  it  follows  that  a  reduc- 
tion of  10%  in  the  price  of  steel,  even  if  passed  on  to  the  ultimate  consumer, 
could  effect  at  most  only  a  1%  reduction  in  the  price  of  the  delivered  automobile, 
which,  as  has  been  stated,  could  bring  about  but  a  1.5%  increase  in  the  number  of 
automobiles  sold  and  in  the  amount  of  steel  used  in  the  automobile  industry. 
The  increased  consumption  arising  out  of  the  extent  to  which  steel  might  be  sub- 
stituted for  some  other  material,  or  the  extent  to  which  the  use  of  steel  per  auto- 
mobile might  be  increased  if  steel  prices  were  reduced,  would  probably  not  increase 
the  elasticity  by  more  than  .1.  Taking  mto  account  all  factors  and  making  a 
liberal  allowance  for  possible  error,  elasticity  of  demand  for  automotive  steel  is 
not  in  excess  of  .2  or  .3. 

The  price  elasticities  for  the  finished  products  or  services  in  the  container,  and 
railroad  industries  have  not  had  the  benefit  of  as  definite  measurement  as  that 
made  of  the  demand  for  automobiles  by  Messrs.  Roos  and  von  Szeliski,  but  the 
evidence  indicates  that  the  demand  for  these  products  is  considerably  less  elastic 
than  the  demand  for  automobiles.  Moreover,  analyses  of  all  the  factors  influenc- 
ing steel  consumption  in  these  industries,  even  assuming  an  elasticity  of  demand 
for  the  finished  products  and  services  as  high  as  2,  show  definitely  that  the  price 
elasticity  of  the  demand  for  steel  in  each  of  the  respective  industries  is  considerably 
less  than  1.  A  mathematical  analysis  of  the  correlation  between  the  amount  of 
all  steel  sold  and  the  various  factors,  including  price,  which  influence  the  quantity 
sold,  reveals  that  a  negligible  portion  of  the  fluctuations  in  the  quantity  sold  are 
attributable  to  price  and  that  a  steel  price  change,  other  factors  reniaining  un- 
changed, will  not  result  in  as  great  a  percentage  change  in  the  volume  of  steel 
sold.  This  confirms  the  individual  analyses  of  the  principal  steel  fconsuming  in- 
dustries already  mentioned. 

While  the  above  analyses  indicate  clearly  that  the  elasticity  of  the  defnand 
for  steel  is  considerably  less  than  1,  it  has  been  assumed  for  the  purposes  of 
this  study,  in  order  to  use  a  figure  that  is  beyond  question,  that  the  elasticity 
of  demand  for  steel  is  as  high  as  1.  An  elasticity  of  1  means  that  any  decrease 
in  price  will  result  in  a  proportional  increase  in  volume  which  will  keep  the  total 
sales  in  dollars  unchanged.  This  is  to  say  that  for  small  changes  in  price  a 
given  percentage  decrease,  such  as  a  5%  reduction  in  price,  will  result  approxi- 
mately in  the  same  percentage  increase  in  volume  sold. 

The  Effect  op  Price  Reductions 

It  is  evident  that  unless  the  elasticity  of  demand  for  the  product  exceeds  1  by 
a  substantial  margin,  the  theory  that  price  reduction  in  and  by  itself  would 
produce  profits  through  increased  volume  is  utterly  fallacious,  not  only  for  the 
United  States  Steel  Corporation,  but  for  any  business  or  any  industry.  Since, 
with  the  elasticity  of  demand  equalling  1,  the  total  sale  receipts  would  remain 
the  same,  for  the  theory  to  work  the  total  costs  of  producing  the  greater  volume 
would  have  to  be  the  same  or  Ijess  than  the  amount  required  to  produce  the 
original  volurpe.  No  increased  payroll  could  be  incurred  to  produce  the  greater 
volume,  for  example.  Such  a  condition  could  exist  only  when  all  costs  were 
"fixed"  or  "overhead"  and  none  were  "additional"  or  "variable".  Only  then 
would  the  cost  per  unit  go  down,  relatively,  as  fast  as  the  volume  went  up. 
Application  of  the  theory  of  increased  profits  through  price  reduction  when  the 
elasticity  of  demand  for  the  product  is  1  or  less  could  thus  result  only  in  loss  to 
the  enterprise  which  adopted  it.  The  actual  amount  to  be  lost  by  reducing 
steel  prices,  however,  and  amount  by  which  the  increase  in  volume  to  be  ex- 
pected as  a  result  of  reducing  steel  prices  falls  short  of  the  increase  needed  to 
offset  the  price  reduction,  can  be  estimated  only  by  including  in  the  computation 
the  relationship  which  exists  between  costs  and  volume. 

The  sales  and  revenues  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation's  subsidiaries 
in  1938  amounted  to  $77.66  per  weighted  ton  of  products  shipped.  Of  this 
amount  $71.86  represented  the  amount  received  from  the  sale  of  goods  and 
$5.80  represented  revenues  from  transportation  and  miscellaneous  operations. 

«  C.  F.  Roos  and  Victor  von  Szeliski,  "Factors  Governing  Changes  in  Domestic  Automobile  Demand." 
The  Dynamics  of  AtUomobilt  Demand,  General  Motors  Corp'n,  N.  Y.,  1939. 


14088 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


On  Chart  3,  the  line  representing  total  costs  as  volume  varies  is  compared  to 
the  corresponding  amount  of  total  sales  and  revenues  at  the  1938  amount  per 
weighted  ton.  This  relationship  indicates  that  the  break-even  point  at  1938 
average  prices  was  at  8.3  million  weighted  tons.  This  is  equivalent  to  an  oper- 
ating rate  of  40%  to  45%  of  capacity,  depending  upon  the  type  of  products 
constituting  the  total  products  shipped. 

A  price  decrease  of  10%  from  the  average  1938  prices,  assuming  that  the 
amount  per  weighted  ton  received  from  transportation  and  other  operations 
remains  unchanged,  would  result  in  total  sales  and  revenues  as  represented  by 
the  dashed  line  in  the  chart. ^     The  result  of  such  a  price  reduction  would  be  to 

Chart  3 


RELATIONSHIP  BETWEEN  SALES  AND  COSTS 

EFFECT  OF  REDUCTION  FROM  AVERAGE  1938  PRICES 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 


1200 


I    I    I    I    I    TH" 


1200 


0     1     2     3     4     5     6     7     8     9    10   11    12    13  14   15   16   17    18 


MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL 
TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 


NOTE;   COSTS  ARE  B«EO  ON  1927.1938  EXPERIENCE,  ADJUSTCO  TO  1933  CONDITIONS 


rai.se  the  break-even  point  to  12.36  million  weighted  tons,  an  increase  of  48.8%, 
which  should  be  contrasted  with  the  11%  increase  in  volume  which  is  the  maxi- 
mum that  might  be  expected  from  a  10%  price  decrease.  The  same  relationship 
holds  not  only  with  regard  to  the  break-even  point,  but  also  with  regard  to  the 
netting  of  any  particular  amount  of  profit  or  loss.  For  instance,  if  production 
amounted  to  6,000,000  weighted  tons,  the  loss  at  1938  average  prices  would  be 
about  $50,500,000.  If  average  1938  prices  were  decreased  10%,  volume 
would  have  to  be  raised  48.8%  to  atout  8,925,000  weighted  tons  in  order  not  to 
increase  the  loss. 

In  this  discussion  it  has  been  assumed  that  the  revenues  from  transportation 
and  miscellaneous  operations  would  increase  sufficiently  as  the  production  of 

'  The  reduction  has  been  made  in  the  $71.86  representing  1938  sales  per  weighted  ton,  but  not  in  the  $5.80 
per  weighted  ton  representing  transportation  and  miscellenaous  revenue. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14089 


steel  increased  so  as  still  to  amount  to  $5.80  per  ton.  The  general  tendency  of 
these  revenues  has  been  to  rise  and  fall  approximately  as  product  shipments  go 
up  and  down,  but  in  recent  years  there  has  been  a  tendency  for  them  to  fall  off 
somewhat  per  ton  of  products  shipped  when  the  higher  levels  of  production  are 
reached.  To  the  extent  that  revenues  from  transportation  and  miscellaneous 
operations  might  fail  to  increase  proportionately  with  increases  in  shipments,  the 
increases  in  volume  needed  to  compensate  for  the  various  price  decreases  would 
be  even  greater  than  those  stated. 

The  impracticabihty  of  attempting  to  raise  volume  from  recession  to  prosperity 
levels  by  means  of  price  decreases  may  be  seen  from  the  effect  of  the  price  reduction 
that  would  have  been  needed  to  bring  the  1938  volume  of  the  Corporation's  sub- 
sidiaries up  to  1937  levels.  Such^an  increase  would  have  been  from  7,800,000  to 
13,200,000  weighted  tons,  a  rise  o*f  69.23%.  Since  steel  has  at  best  an  elasticity 
of  demand  of  1,  such  an  increase  could  have  been  brought  through  price  reduction, 
if  at  all,  only  by  a  price  decrease  of  at  least  40.9%,  reducing  sales  per  weighted  ton 
from  $71.86  to  $42.46.^  Disregarding  the  possibility  that  other  operations  might 
not  expand  with  increased  shipments  and  adding  in  the  full  $5.80  per  weighted  ton 
realized  from  other  operations  at  actual  1938  volume,  the  total  sales  and  operating 
revenues  would  then  have  amounted  to  $48.26  per  weighted  ton.  Since  the  vari- 
able cash  costs  amount  to  $53.36  per  weighted  ton,  the  Corporation's  subsidiaries 
would  have  sustained  a  cash  loss  of  $5.10  on  every  weighted  ton  sold  in  addition 
to  failing  to  recover  any  part  of  the  fixed  cash  costs  of  $152,600,000.  Assuming 
that  the  price  reduction  would  have  been  successful  in  restoring  the  1937  volume, 
13,200,000  weighted  tons  would  have  been  sold.  At  a  loss  of  $5.10  a  ton,  plus 
$152,600,000  fixed  costs  not  covered  by  the  sales  price,  the  Corporation  and  its 
subsidiaries  would  have  had  a  cash  loss  for  the  year  of  $219,920,000.  This  is 
without  making  any  provision  for  depreciation  and  depletion  of  fixed  assets.  The 
drain  of  such  a  cash  loss  upon  the  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries,  if  continued, 
would  have  exhausted  their  1938  average  working  capital  in  less  than  two  years. 
If  the  amount  of  the  depreciation  and  depletion  of  assets  at  this  volume  of  opera- 
tions, amounting  to  $60,784,000,  is  added  to  the  cash  loss,  there  is  a  total  loss  of 
$280,704,000.  Annual  losses  at  this  rate  would  wipe  out  the  combined  equity  of 
the  preferred  and  common  stockholders  as  of  December  31,  1938,  In  about  four 
and  a  half  years. 

While  a  smaller  decrease  in  price  could  not  have  been  expected  to  raise  the  1938 
volume  to  the  1937  level,  it  may  nevertheless  be  contended  that  some  price  reduc- 
tion and  some  resulting  stimulation  in  volume  were  desirable.  At  1938  average 
prices,  however,  the  increase  in  volume  which  would  take  place  even  if  the  elasticity 
of  demand  in  steel  were  as  high  as  1  would  be  far  short  of  the  percentage  increase 
needed  to  prevent  additional  loss.  The  increases  in  volume  needed  to  offset 
various  percentage  reductions  in  price  and  the  maximum  probable  increase  in 
volume  which  would  result  are  as  follows: 


Table  3. — Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Various  Decreases  in 
Average  1938  Prices — Compared  to  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume — 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Percentage  Reduc- 
tion in  Price 

Percentage 

Increase  in 

Volume 

Needed 

Probable 
Percentage 
Increase,  As- 
suming Elas- 
ticity of  1 

Percentage  Reduc- 
tion in  Price 

Percentage 

Increase  in 

Volume 

Needed 

Probable 
Percentage 
Increase,  As- 
suming Elas- 
ticity of  1 

J 

3.4 
7.0 
10.9 
15.1 
19.6 
24.5 
29.8 
35.5 
41.8 

1.0 
2.0 
3.1 
4.2 
5.3 
6.4 
7.5 
.   8.7 
9.9 

10 

48.8 
56.4 
64.8 
74.2 
84.8 
96.7 
190.3 
453.-6 
5, 858.  2 

11 . 

12 

13 : 

14. 

15 

20 

25 

25  0 

8 

33  3 

g 

30 

42  9 

The  divergence  between  the  needed  increase  in  volume  and  the  maximum  probable 
resulting  increase,  based  on  an  elasticit,v  of  1,  is  illust  ated  in  Chart  4. 

The  following  tabulation  sets  forth  what  the  additional  loss  in  dollars  to  the 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  would  have  been  if  the  1938 


« If  the  elasticity  of  demand  were  1,  the  total  sales  in  dollars  would  remain  unchanged  by  price  reductions 
since  volume  would  increase  to  a  compensating  extent.  Hence  dividing  the  1938  sales  of  .$560,508,000  by 
13,200,000  will  give  the  average  price  at  which  steel  would  have  to  have  been  sold  to  have  shipped  13,200.000 
weighted  tons  in  1938. 


14090 


OONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


average  prices  had  been  reduced  various  percentages.  Separate  estimates  have 
been  made  showing  the  additional  loss  if  the  maximum  probable  increase  in  volume 
resulted  and  if  no  increase  in  volume  resulted  from  the  price  reduction.  The 
actual  loss  would  have  to  fall  somewherebetween  these  two  limits. 

Chart  4 


INCREASES  IN  VOLUME  NEEDED  TO  COMPENSATE  FOR 

VARIOUS  DECREASES  IN  1938  PRICES 

COMPARED  TO  PROBABLE  RESULTING  INCREASES  IN  VOLUME 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

240 


220 


? 

180 

n 

^ 

160 

z 

140 

s 

12U 

:^ 

Ul 

ion 

80 

Q- 

60 

40 

20 

n 

r 

r 

n 

n 

' 

„r 

P 

I 

V 

REA 
OL 
ED 

SES 

JM 
ED 

n 

I 

.-.- 

.;.: 

'' 

■ 

,/:' 

..jjM- 

probable 
resulting 
'increases 
in  volume 


0    1    2    3    4    5    6    7    8    9   10  11  12  13  14  15  16  17  13  19  20  21 
PERCENTAGE  DECREASES  FROM  AVERAGE  1938  PRICES 


NOTE;    PROBA>iLE  RESULTING  INCREASES  IN  VOLUME  BASED  IN  ASSUMPTION  THAT  ELASTICITY  OF  DCMAND  EQUALS 


Table  4. — Estimated  Additions  to  1988  Deficit — How  Deficit  Would  Have  Increased 
if  Average  1938  Prices  Had  Been  Reduced — United  States  Steel  Corporation  and 
Subsidiaries 


.  Percentage  Re- 
duction in  Price 

Estimated 
Addition  to 
Deficit  Assum- 
ing Elasticity 
of  Demand  for 
Steel  of  1 

Estimated 
Addition  to 
Deficit  if  No 
Increase  ip  Vol- 
ume Resulted 
from  Price 
Reduction 

Percentage  Re- 
duction in  Price 

Estimated 
Addition  to 
Deficit  Assum- 
ing Elasticity 
of  Demand  for 
Steel  of  1 

Estimated 
Addition  to 
Deficit  if  No 
Increase  In  Vol- 
ume Resulted 
from  Price 
Reduction 

1... 

$3,900,000 
7,900,000 
12,000,000 
16, 200, 000 
20,  500.  000 
24, 900, 000 
29,  300, 000 
33,900,000 
38,  500, 000 
43, 300, 000 

$5,600,000 
11,200,000 
16,  §00, 000 
22,400;  000 
28,000,000 
33,  600, 000 
39,  200, 000 
44, 800,  000 
50,  400, 000 
56, 100,  000 

11 

48, 100, 000 
53, 100, 000 
58, 200, 000 
63,  400,  000 
68,  700, 000 
74,  200, 000 
79,  800, 000 
85,  500,  000 
91. 400. 000 
97,400,000 

61,700,000 
67,  300, 000 
72, 900, 000 
78, 500, 000 
84,100,000 
89  700  000 

2...    . 

12 

3 

13 

4 

14 

5 

15 

6...: 

16 

7 

17 

95  300  000 

8 

18 

100  900  000 

9 

106,500,000 
112,100,000 

10 

GONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14091 


The  1938  operating  deficit,  before  Federal  income  tax,  and  the  additional 
losses  that  would  have  resulted  from  price  reductions 'if  volume  increased  to  the 
same  relative  extent  that  prices  decreased,  are  illustrated  in  Chart  5. 

Since  the  average  1938  prices  represent  the  average  results  of  prices  in  effect 
both  before  and  after  the  June  24,  1938,  reduction  in  the  price  of  steel  products, 
Chart  6  has  been  constructed  to  show  the  relationship  between  annual  sales  a,nd 
revenues  and  annual  costs  at  various  levels  of  production  if  the  prices  prevailing 
in  the  second  half  of  1938  had  prevailed  over  the  entire  year  J     At  such  a  price 

Chart  5  '  . 


ESTIMATED  ADDITIONS  TO  1938  DEFICIT 

HOW  DEFICIT  WOULD  HAVE  INCREASED  IF  PRICES  HAD  BEEN  REDUCED 
AND  VOLUME  HAD  INCREASED  TO  SAME  RELATIVE  EXTENT 

U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 
96  — 872 


nt 


ESTIMATED  ADDITIONS  TO 

DEFICIT  IF  PRICES  HAD  BEEN 

REDUCED  AS  IND.CATED 


ACTUAL  1938  DEFICIT  I  I  ■  I  ■  I 

■■■■■■mill 

1     2    3    4    5    6     7    8    9    10  11  12  13  14  15  16  17  18 

PERCENTAGE  REDUCTION  IN  1938  AVERAGE  PRICE 


level  the  break-even  point  for  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  its  sub- 
sidiaries would  be  at  about  ten  and  a  half  million  of  weighted  tons,  which  is  equiv- 
alent to  an  operating  rate  of  50%  to  55%  of  capacity,  depending  on  the  type  of 
products  predominating.  A  10%  reduction  in  prices  at  this  level  would  result 
in  sales  and  revenues  indicated  by  the  dashed  line  in  Chart  6.  The  total  sales 
and  revenues  would  then  reach  the  amount  of  the  total  costs  only  if  operations 
were  around  90%  of  capacity.  If  the  break-even  point  were  this  high,  the  Cor- 
poration's subsidiaries  would  have  to  operate  at  the  impossible  annual  rate  of 
over  130%  of  capacity  to  earn  a  return,  before  income  taxes,  as  modest  as  5%  on 
their  investment  in  tangible  assets. 

'  The  amount  of  sales  and  revenues  per  weighted  ton  if  the  prices  prevailing  in  the  second  half  of  1938 
had- prevailed  throughout  the  entire  year  has  been  estimated  by  reducing  the  sales  per  weighted  ton  propor- 
tionately to  the  extent  to  which  the  selling  value  per  weighted  ton  of  rolled  and  finished  steel  products 
shipped  during  the  second  half  of  1938  was  less  than  the  average  selling  value  of  rolled  and  finished  products 
for  the  entire  year. 


124491— 41— pt.  2€ 


-33 


14092 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


The  percentage  increases  in  volume  required  to  ofifset  a  given  percentage  de- 
crease in  the  average  price  prevailing  in  the  second  half  of  1938,  as  shown  in  Table 
5  below,  would  be  even  greater  than  those  needed  at  the  average  level  of  prices 
for  1938  as  a  whole. 

Table  5. — Increases  in  Volume  Needed  to  Compensate  for  Various  Decreases  in 
Snd  Half,  1938,  Prices  Corn-pared  to  Probable  Resulting  Increases  in  Volume — 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  Subsidiaries 


Percentage  Reduc- 
tion in  Price 

Percentage 

Increase  in 

Volume 

Needed 

Probable 
Percentage 
Increase, 
Assuming 
Elasticity  of  1 

Percentage  Reduc- 
tion in  Price 

Percentage 

Increase  in 

Volume 

Needed 

Probable 
Percentage 
Increase, 
Assuming 
Elasticity  oil 

4.0 
8.4 
13.1 
18.3 
24.0 
30.2 
37.2 
44.8 
53.5 

1.0 
2.0 
3.1 
4.2 
5.3 
6.4 
7.5 
8.7 
9.9 

10 

63.1 
74.1 
86.7 
101.3 
118.3 

342!  6 
2984.4 

11.1 

2 

11 

12.4 

3 

12 — 

13.6 

4 

13 

14.9 

5 

14 - 

16.3 

g 

15 

17.7 

7 

20 .— 

25.0 

g 

25 

33.3 

9                      

Chart  6 


RELATIONSHIP  BETWEEN  SALES  AND  COSTS 

EFFECT  OF  REDUCTION  FROM  2nd  HALF  1938  PRICES 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 


1200 


1200 


0     1     2     3     4     5    6     7     8     9    10   11    12   13  14   15  16  17 
^  MILLIONS  OF  WEIGHTED  TONS  OF  ALL 

TONNAGE  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED 


NOTE.   COSTS  ARE  BASED  ON  1927- 1938  DPERIENCE,  ADJUSTED  TO  193S  CONOITIONS 


CJONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14093 

The  divergence  between  the  needed  increase  in  volume  and  the  maximum  probable 
increase  to  result  from  a  reduction  in  the  prices  prevailing  in  the  second  half  of 
1938  is  graphically  portrayed  on  Chart  7.^ 

The  inter-relationship  between  prices  and  sales,  costs,  and  volume  for  the 
United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries,  then,  is  such  that  the  increase 
in  volume  required  to  offset  a  price  decrease  is  far  greater,  than  the  price  reduction 
could  be  expected  to  stimulate.  Hence,  in  times  of  recession  the  Corporation 
and  its  subsidiaries,  unhappily,  do  not  have  the  alternative  of  lowering  their 
prices,  moving  their  goods  and  employing  their  workers.  Reduction  of  prices 
beyond  that  necessary  to  meet  competition  and  keep  their  shaje  of  the  going 
business,  can  result  only  in  severely  increasing  the  financial  losses  which  are 
incurred  in  such  periods.  Instead^  of  prosperity,  undiminished  employment,  and 
.undiminished  payrolls  in  the  steel  industry,  only  bankruptcy,  unemployment  and 
dwindling  payrolls  would  result  from  further  price  reduction. 

»  While  the  assumption  of  any  elasticity  of  demand  for  steel  greatipr  than  1  is  highly  unrealistic,  it  Is  inter- 
esting to  note  that  even  if  steel  had  an  elasticity  of  1.5  or  2,  the  percentage  increase  in  volume,  needed  to 
offset  a  price  reduction  would  still  greatly  exceed  the  percentage  increase  in  volame  which  would  then  result 
from  reducing  prices: 


Resulting  Increase  to  Volume 

Increase  to  Volume  Needed  to 
Oflset: 

Decrease  in  Price 

If  E'c3ticlty= 

If  Elasticity = 

Decrease  in 
Average  1938 
Steel  Prices 

Decrease  to  2d 
Half  1938 
Steel  Prices 

1% 

1.6% 

3.1 

4.7 

6.3 

8.0 
17.1 
27.6 
39.8 
54.0 
70.8 

.0% 

6.3 

8.6 
11.1 
23.5 
38.4 
56.3 
77.8 
1011 

3.4% 
7.0 
10.9 
15.1 
19.6 
48.8 
96.7 
190.3  . 
463.6 
5858.2 

4.0% 

2    " " 

8.4 

3 

13.1 

4 

18.3 

5 

24.0 

10 

63.1 

15 

138.4 

20 

342.6 

25 

2984.4 

30 

(No  increase 
sufficient) 

14Q94 


OONCJENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Chakt  7 


INCREASES  IN  VOLUME  NEEDED  TO  COMPENSATE  FOR 
'       VARIOUS  DECREASES  IN  2nd  HALF  1938  PRICES 
COMPARED  TO  PROBABLE  RESULTING  INCREASES  IN  VOLUME 
U.  S.  STEEL  CORPORATION  AND  SUBSIDIARIES 

440  ; _ 


2  3  4  5  6  7  8  9  10  U  12  13  14  15  16  17  18  19  20  21 
PERCENTAGE  DECREASES  IN  PRICES 


NOTE:    PROBABLE  RESULTING  INCREASES  IN  VOLUME  BASED  IN  ASSUMPTION  THAT  C'JVSTICITY  OF  DEMAND  EQUALS  I 


'Exhibit  No.  1418"  is  included  in  Hearings,  Part  27,  appendix,  p.  1419. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14095 

Exhibit  No.  2180 
THE  DISTRIBUTION  OF  STEEL  TO  MAJOR  CONSUMING  INDUSTRIES 

This  is  an  analysis  prepared  by  the  Special  Economic  Research  Section  of  United 
States  Steel  Corporation,  composed  of  Messrs.  Edward  T.  Dickinson,  Jr.,  Ernest 
M.  Doblin,  H.  Gregg  Lewis,  Jacob  L.  Mosak,  Mandal  R.  Segal,  Dwight  B. 
Yntema  and  Miss  Marion  W.  Worthing.  The  work  of  this  group  was  under  the 
supervision  of  Theodore  O.  Yntema,  Professor  of  Statistics,  University  of  Chicago. 
This  analysis  was  written  by  Marion  W.  Worthing  and  has  had  the  benefit  of 
suggestions  from  other  members  of  the  staflF.  It  is  issued  by  United  States  Steel 
Corporation. 

October  30,  1939. 

description  o^  the  problems 

The  table  presented  on  pages  2  and  3  of  this  memorandum  shows  yearly  esti- 
mates of  the  tonnage  of  steel  production  destined  for  each  of  the  major  consuming 
industries  from  1923  to  1938.  The  estimates  presented  in  this  table  have  been 
prepared  because  statistics  covering  the  full  distribution  of  either  production  or 
shipment  from  year  to  year  are  not  available. 

Estimates  of  the  amount  of  steel  distributed  to  the  major  consuming  industries 
have  been  published  every  year  since  1922  or  1923  by  Iron  Age  and  Steel  maga-- 
zines.  These  estimates  are  based  on  annual  reports  by  individual  steel  producers 
of  shipments  of  the  major  classes  of  steel  products  to  each  type  of  consumer. 
Although  each  trade  journal  sends  out  its  own  requests  for  data  to  the  steel  pro- 
ducers, the  information  asked  for  and  received  by  each  publication  is  similar. 
The  figures  published  by  each  of  these  magazines  have  been  used  in  this  study. 
Because  of  variable  coverage  of  firms  from  year  to  year,  and  because  of  ambiguities 
and  variations  in  classifications,  the  tabulations  resulting  from  the  combination  of 
the  reports  of  the  contributing  steel  companies  do  not  represent  accurately  the 
distribution  of  steel  by  consuming  industries. 

In  an  attempt  to  remedy  some  of  the  defects  in  the  original  shipment  tables,  a 
series  of  adjustments  have  been  made  which  will  be  presented  in  detail  later  in  this 
report  but  which  may  be  described  here  briefly  as  follows: 

1.  Distribution  percentages  derived  from  the  original  shipment  data  were  ap- 
plied to  hot-rolled  steel  -production  in  order  to  secure  comparability  of  the  totals 
among  the  different  years,  i.  e.,  the  percentage  distribution  of  the  shipments  of  each 
class  of  product  to  the  major  industries  was  applied  to  the  production  of  the  most 
nearly  comparable  hot-rolled  products. 

2.  Production  indicated  for  jobbers,  warehouses,  and  similar  distributors  was 
reallocated  to  the  appropriate  consuming  industries  on  the  basis  of  the  informed 
opinion  of  a  number  of  persons  concerned  with  the  sale  of  merchant  products. 


14090 


OONOENTRATION  OF  FCONOAIIC  TOWER 


3~ 


ioot-coooa)r-0":it^air-as»0'«fQ 

^  ^  ^  ^  ^*  ^  r^  ,_r  r^  ,-r  r-T  ,-H  M  Cf  Cf  r 


5(Nt--OJ(NO'-'OOSCOCOt 


S?3gg 


oofeS< 


5  05OO00O  J 


:^^  OsaiCOC^C^COOOr-HOOOiiOC 

"^  ^^  CD  <©  r^  CO '^  c^  c^*"  CO  CO  »o  lo ' 


isslBSIISSsKis 


Tj4-(tiiOCDcOt^t-CD-' 


^:SS3f 


«   ! 


DOTS°iS«S2ot^S3 

h  CD  O -^  C^  ^""  CO  1*"  CD  to  CD  M 


>6503CTsosoio>coo>d05050iCiaac 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14097 


3  s 
3^ 


SSoSSSSS 


5-cf-rci-iNmv"*"< 


CT  lO  CD  iO  »0  UO  CO -^  cf  r-T  CO  IN  CO  « to*  ■■ 


^         -•-— "--^-M-c 


;§i3§iisl 


iiglBiiliiililis 


J(5cOCOt^-^»00>'-tCOC5»0»0 


?S§K§S:^SSS 


CO^Oi<NC^C»c3iOOC»OJC 


^8§ 


Cos 

li-s 

®  o  ^ 


.9-,:  "5 
|2    g 


■-  S   "a 

-Si  I 

ill 


11  i 

W;'3      '^ 

ll  I 

Q  ~    •  •  II: 

:s§  I? 

:§l    is 

I        ^ 


14098       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

SUMMARY    AND    EVALUATION    OF    RESULTS 

The  final  series  presented  in  the  accompanying  tables  represent  the  annual 
domestic  hot-rolled  steel  production  estimated  to  have  been  consumed  eventually 
by  the  major  steel  consuming  industries,  either  as  hot-rolled  steel  or  in  further 
finished  forms.  The  products  destined  for  export  are  included  in  a  separate 
group  in  these  tabulations  but  the  consumption  of  imported  iron  and  steel  is  not 
included  in  the  table. 

The  total  estimated  consumption  of  hot-rolled  steel  by  industry  groups  is 
shown  as  computed  on  the  basis  of  both  Iron  Age  and  Steel  data.  It  is  impossible 
to  determine  whether  the  results  based  upon  Iron  Age  or  those  based  on  Steel  are 
more  reliable.  Because  of  the  confidential  nature  of  the  data  from  reporting 
companies,  there  is  no  chance  to  judge  the  accuracy  of  the  methods  used  in 
making  either  magazine's  compilations.  By  comparing  the  movements  of  these 
consumption  series  with  other  measures  of  activity  in  the  various  industries,  it 
is  possible  that  some  evaluation  may  be  made  of  particular  estimates.  This 
process,  however,  is  diflicult,  time-consuming,  and  subject  to  error. 

Although  the  final  series  retain  some  of  the  deficiencies  which  were  inherent 
in  the  basic  data,  it  is  nevertheless  reasonable  to  state  that  the  adjusted  figures 
are  in  most  respects  more  useful  and  more  trustworthy  than  the  original  ones. 
In  the  first  place,  by  aUpcating  total  hot-roUed  steel  production  to  industry 
classes  on  the  basis  of  reported  shipments,  the  resulting  series  become  comparable 
from  year  to  year.  Further,  because  the  secondary  distribution  of  steel  does  not 
follow  the  same  pattern  as  that  typical  of  direct  shipments  from  the  mills  to  the 
consumers,  it  is  more  realistic  to  make  an  approximate  allocation  of  jobber 
tonnages  to  industries  that  customarily  buy  from  those  sources  than  to  ignore 
such  distribution.  In  many  instances  a  comparison  of  the  estimated  distribution 
calculated  from  figures  based  on  Iron  Age  and  Steel  show  consistent  results. 
Where  the  discrepancies  between  the  figures  are  large  the  variation  can  be  ac- 
counted for  in  some  instances  by  differences  in  industry  classifications  used  by 
the  compilers  of  the  original  data. 

Adjustment  Procedures 

NOTE  ON  THE  DISTRIBUTION  DATA  PUBLISHED  BY  IRON    lGE  AND  STEEL 

The  compilation  of  steel  shipment  data  was  started  by  both  Iron  Age  and  Steel 
in  "about  1922.  Since  it  was  not  possible  for  the  trade  journals  to  get  very  com- 
plete coverage  in  the  earlier  years,  the  figures  for  the  first  two  or  three  years  are 
rather  heavily  weighted  with  data  for  the  subsidiaries  of  United  States  Steel 
Corporation.  Even  now,  a  few  small  companies  do  not  report  their  shipments. 
The  coverage  was  improved  rather  rapidly  but  at  no  time  has  it  been  complete 
nor  has  it  been  the  same  from  year  to  year.  Although  the  published  tables  are 
often  described  as  representing  a  specified  percentage  of  the  steel  industry's 
ingot  producing  or  finishing  capacity,  it  is  not  possible  to  use  these  percentagee 
as  bases  for  raising  the  tonnage  figures  to  an  assumed  100  percent  because  the 
shipments  of  certain  products  were  more  completely  reported  than  others.  Until 
1938,  each  publication  was  anxious  to  print  the  distribution  table  in  its  annual 
statistical  number,  the  first  issue  in  January.  Since  shipment  data  for  the 
entire  preceding  calendar  year  could  not  be  collected  before  this  publication  date, 
the  steel  producers  reported  estimated  shipments  for  December  or  for  both 
November  and  December.  It  is  probable  that  these  estimates,  did  not  deviate 
seriously  in  relative  distribution  by  industries  from  the  shipments  actually  going 
to  consumers.  In  1937  and  1938  the  tabulations  were  delayed  so  as  to  allow  for 
more  complete  reports.  Every  year,  each  publication  has  made  it  a  practice  to 
publish  some  data  for  preceding  years,  presumably  for  purposes  of  comparison. 
Uafortunately,  the  components  of  these  figures  and  percentages  for  the  various 
yftars  differ  in  many  instances  so  thpt  they  are  not  strictly  comparable.  The  only 
figures  used  in  making  the  present  computations  were  the  basic  tables  showing 
tonnages  both  by  product  and  by  industry. 

ADJUSTMENT    OF   DISTHlSUTION   TO    PRODUCTION    DATA 

Since  the  published  shipment  tables  were  not  comparable  in  their  original  form 
and  did  not  cover  the  entire  industry  and  since  there  are  no  data  available  on 
total  steel  shiprrents,  it  seemed  best  to  use  the  proportions  indicated  by  the 
shipments  to  allocate  hot-rolled  steel  production  to  the  ultimate  users.'     Aoord- 

'  Practically  all  the  stoel  products  wblcB  aro  shipped  may  bo  classified  as  hot-rolled  products  or  «r«  tke 
result  of  the  further  finishing  of  hot-rolled  products. 


OONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       14099 

'agly,  the  percentage  distribution  by  industry  of  each  class  of  products  for  which 
shipments  were  reported  separately  was  applied  to  the  appropriate  hot-roiled 
iron  and  steel  production.  The  resulting  series  have  the  advantage  of  being 
derived  from  totals  which  are  comparable  from  year  to  year,  which  represent 
practically  the  entire  production  in  the  country,  and  which  contain  no  duplica- 
tions. It  is  reasonable  to  expect  that,  to  the  extent  that  the  various  shipment 
figures  reported  in  different  years  are  representative  of  all  shipments,  the  per- 
centages going  to  diflferent  industries  derived  from  the  reported  shipments  should 
be  adequate  for  allocating  production  data  to  ultimate  consuming  classes.  Pro- 
duction and  shipments  for  any  given  year  are,  of  course,  unlikely  to  be  identical 
but  they  are  probably  not  very  dififerent.  The  main  discrepancies  between  them 
arise  from  variations  in  the  inventories  of  finished  steel  held  by  steel  producers  at 
the  end  of  each  year.  There  are  no  figures  available  by  which  the  condition  of 
these  inventories  can  be  ascertained,  but  it  seems,  from  the  opinion  of  various 
persons  concerned  with  such  matters,  that  relatively  little  finished  steel  is  cus- 
tomarily stored  and  the  amounts  that  are  kept  on  hand  as  stock  do  not  ordinarily 
change  radically  from  year  to  year. 

INDUSTRY  CLASSIFICATIONS 

It  is  probable  that  the  greatest  errors  inherent  in  the  shipment  data  arise  from 
inconsistent  industry  classifications  of  consumers  on  the  part  of  the  reporting  steel 
companies.  Some  companies  made  careful  reports  of  their  shipments  based  on 
standard  systems  of  customer  classification,  but  at  least  a  few  others  make  rather 
inadequate  ones.  Certain  companies  do  not  appear  to  have  had  or  do  not  now 
have  records  suitable  for  accurately  reporting  shipments  by  industry  groups. 
Fortunately,  data  for  these  companies  that  have  been  reported  most  incompletely 
have  usually  been  segregated  from  the  others  in  the  published  tables.  The  trade 
journals  have  endeavored  to  check  back  on  the  reports  and  have  asked  for  recals- 
sifications  when  they  have  detected  obvious  mistakes,  but  it  has  been  impossible 
to  eliminate  all  errors.  Since  the  present  adjustments  have  been  made  for  much 
broader  industry  groups  that  thoselshown  in  the  original  published  tabulations, 
it  is  hoped  that  many  of  the  misclassifications  indicated  above  do  not  affect  them. 
The  combinations  of  industry  subgroups  into  the  larger  classes  were  made  with 
the  advice  of  the  persons  on  the  respective  staffs  of  Iron  Age  and  Steel  responsible 
for  the  tabulations.     A  list  of  the  industry  sub-groups  is  shown  in  Appendix  B. 

PRODUCT   CLASSIFICATIONS 

Relatively  few  difficulties  arose  from  the  product  classification,  primarily 
because  there  has  been  little  variation  in'  the  product  classes  over  the  entire 
period,  except  that  in  some  of  the  earlier  years  merchant  and  concrete  bars  were 
combined  and  galvanized  sheets  were  included  with  all  other  sheets.  In  the 
adjustment  of  each  published  product  total,  the  most  nearly  comparable  hot- 
roUed  production  was  carefully  chosen  and  the  selection  of  products  for  these 
classes  was  checked  with  the  editors  of  Iron  Age  and  Steel.  A  list  of  the  product 
classes  currently  used  by  Iron  Age  and  Steel  and  the  group  of  hot-rolled  products 
related  to  each  class  in  the  computations  are  shown  in  Appendix  C. 

JOBBERS,    WAREHOUSES,    AND    OTHER   DISTRIBUTORS 

From  15  to  20  percent  of  the  finished  steel  shipped  each  year  goes  to  jobbers, 
warehouses,  and  other  distributors  *  who,  in  turn,  resell  the  steel  to  the  same 
types  of  consumers  as  those  who  take  their  shipments  direct  from  the  mill. 
Because  certain  products,  at  least,  are  distributed  through  jobbers  to  the  various 
consuming  industries  in  different  proportions  from  those  typical  for  direct  salec, 
it  is  desirable  to  reallocate  the  jobber  shipments  to  consuming  groups.  In  the 
absence  of  any  statistical  basis,  allocations  have  been  made,  product  by  product, 
on  the  basis  of  advice  from  a  number  of  people  familiar  with  the  uses. and  distri- 
bution channels  of  the  various  products.  The  methods  employed  in  these  adjust- 
ments and  reasons  for  their  use  are  described  below. 

Since  the  proportion  of  rails  and  track  accessories  handled  by  jobbers  is  insig- 
nificant, the  actual  tonnages  reported  in  all  years  were,  for  convenience,  assigned 
to  miscellaneous  industries.  For  the  most  part,  the  shipment  of  plates,  shapes, 
merchant  bars,  black  plate  for  tinning,  strip,  and  all  other  sheets  other  than  galva- 
nized which  are  distributed  by  jobbers  appear  to  go  to  much  the  same  consuming 
industries  in  about  the  same  proportions  as  do  the  ishipments  resulting  from  mill 

*  For  simplicity  all  types  of  distributors  will  be  referred  to  here  as  jobbers. 


14100  GONOENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

sales.     Consequently,  the  jobber  tonnages  for  these  products  were  allocated  to 
the  consuming  industries  in  the  same  proportions  as  direct  sales. 

Three  product  groups,  galvanized  sheets,  pipes  and  tubes,  and  wire  products, 
appear  to  have  different  distribution  pattersn  through  jobbers  than  in  direct 
sales.  Special  inquiries  were  made  concerning  the  jobber  sales  of  these  products 
and  the  following  methods  of  allocation  were  adopted,  based  on  the  information 
collected : 

1.  Galvanized  Sheets: 

(a)  50%  to  the  construction  industry  for  roofing  ventilating,  etc. 

(b)  10%  to  agriculture  for  bins,  tanks,  etc. 

(c)  40%  to  miscellaneous  industries,  including  sheet  metal  shops,  air- 

conditioning,  etc. 

2.  Pipes  and  Tubes: 

(a)  Total  production  of  line  pipe  and  oil  country  goods  was  allocated 

to  the  oil,  gas,  and  water  industry.  Whenever  the  estimated 
production  of  skelp  and  rounds  necessary  for  conversion  to  line 
pipe  and  oil  country  goods  differed  from  the  tonnage  of  skelp  and 
rounds  allocated  to  the  industry  on  the  basis  of  the  original  figures, 
the  difference  was  adjusted  by  adding  or  subtracting  the  required 
tonnage  from  the  amount  originally  allocated  to  jobbers. 

(b)  The  remaining  jobber  tonnage  was  split  between  mechanical  tubing 

and  a  combined  tonnage  of  standard  pipe,  boiler  tubes,  and  all 
other  pipe. 

(c)  Mechanical  tubing  was  allocated  40%  to  automotive,  40%  to  ma- 

chinery, and  20%  to  miscellaneous  industries. 

(d)  Other  pipe  was  distributed  50%  to  construction,  25%  to  agriculture, 

and  25%  to  miscellaneous  industries. 

3.  Wire  Products  were  Allocated: 

(a)  35%  to  agriculture. 

(b)  40%  to  construction  (including  repairs). 

(c)  25%  to  miscellaneous. 

Appendix  A.   Miscellaneous  Notes  on  Procedure 

1.  In  1938  both  Iron  Age  and  Steel  included  railroad  buildings  and  bridges  under 
construction  instead  of  under  railroads  as  was  formerly  the  case.  In  order  to  make 
these  classes  reasonably  consistent  with  previous  years,  transfers  of  plates,  shapes, 
and  merchant  bars  were  made  to  railroads  from  construction  based  on  the  pro- 
portions of  these  products  Used  for  railroad  buildings  and  bridges  in  recent  years. 

2.  All  concrete  bars  handled  through  jobbers  have  been  transferred  to  construc- 
tion in  the  first  adjustments. 

3.  For  1923,  1924  and  1925  shipments  through  jobbers  reported  by  Iron  Age 
were  allocated  to  industry  classes  by  the  compilers. 

4.  Miscellaneous  industries  should  not  be  compared  through  all  the  years  unless 
furniture  and  furnishings,  etc.,  are  added. 

5.  Before  1933  the  Iron  Age  did  not  report  galvanized  sheets  separately.  For 
previous  years  65%  of  the  jobber  tonnage  of  sheets  was  allocated  as  galvanized 
sheets  and  the  remainder  as  ordinary  sheets. 

6.  All  shipments  of  plates,  shapes,  bars  and  pipes  originally  allocated  to  the 
container  industry  were  transferred  to  construction. 

Appendix  B.  Industry  Sub-Groups  Included  in  Major  CoNSUMiNa  Industry 

Groups 

Automotive — Automobiles,  trucks,  parts,  etc.  (tractors  in  some  years)."" 
Railroads — Trackwork,  cars  and  locomotives,  parts,  railroad  buildings  and  bridges. 
Agriculture — Implements,  equipment,  other  farm  uses,  tractors  in  some  years. 
Construction—  fabricators,  building  contractors,  concrete  reinforcing  companies, 

building  hardware  and  trim  companies,  concrete  bar  jobbers,  highways,  boiler 

and  tank  makers,  power  developments,   containers  made  from  heavy  steel 

products. 
Shipbuilding — Ships,  boats,  barges. 

Containers  light — Made  from  light  steel  products,  predominantly  tin  cans. 
Machinery— Machinery,  hand  tools,  electrical  machinery  and  equipment. 
Oil,  gas  and  water — Oil,  gas  and  water. 

Mining,  lumbering  and  quarrying — Mining,  lumbering  and  quarrying. 
Furniture  and  furnishings — Furniture  and  stove  makers,  domestic  appliances, 

refrigerators,  office  equipment. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       14101 

Miscellaneous — Bolt,  niit  and  rivei  makers,  forgers,  pressed  and  formed  metal 
manufacturers. 

Appendix  C.  Hot-Rolled  Product  Combinations  Used  in  Adjusting  Iron 
Age  and  Steel  Shipment  Data 

Rails — Heavy,  light,  girder,  and  high  tee. 

Track  accessories — Long  splice  bars,  tie  plate  bars,  and  cross  ties. 

Structural  shapes — Heavy  structural  shapes  and  sheet  piling. 

Plates — Sheared  and  universal. 

Bars — Merchant  bars  (carbon  and  alloy)  and  light  shapes. 

Concrete  bars — Concrete  bars,  including  those  reroUed  from  old  material. 

Black  plate — Black  plate  for  tinning  onlv  (combined  with  strip  and  strips  for 
tinning  in  1938). 

Galvanized  sheets — Galvanized  sheets  a  I'l  galvanized  formed  products. 

Sheets — Hot-rolled  sheets  minus  galvanized  sheets  and  galvanized  formed  prod- 
ucts plus  all  black  plate  other  than  black  plate  for  tinning. 

Strip — Strip,  hoops,  bands,  and  cotton  ties. 

Pipes  and  tube — Skelp  and  blanks  or  rounds  for  piercing. 

Wire  products — Wire  rods. 

All  other — Rolled  forging  billets,  blooms  and  billets  for  export,' car  wheels  and 
other  hot-rolled  products. 


Exhibit  No.  2181 

INDEXES  OF  MILL-NET  YIELDS  ON  PRODUCTS  SHIPPED  BY  UNITED 
STATES  STEEL  CORPORATION  SUBSIDIARIES 

This  is  an  analysis  prepared  by  the  Special  Economic  Research  Section  of 
United  States  Steel  Corporation,  composed  of  Messrs.  Edward  Tt  Dickinson,  Jr., 
Ernest  M.  Doblin,  H.  Gregg  Lewis,  Jacob  L.  Mosak,  Mandal  R.  Segal,  Dwight 
B.  Yntema  and  Miss  Marion  W.  Worthing.  The  work  of  this  group  was  under 
the  supervision  of  Theodore  O.  Yntema,  Professor  of  Statistics,  University  of 
Chicago.  This  analysis  was  written  by  Marion  W.  Worthing  and  has  had  the 
benefit  of  suggestions  from  other  members  of  the  staff.  It  is  issued  by  United 
States  Steel  Corporation. 

November  1,  1939. 

Purpose 

The  purpose  of  this  memorandum  is  to  describe  the  construction  of  several 
index  numbers  which  have  been  prepared  from  mill-net  yield  ^  figures  for  the 
major  steel  products  shipped  to  the  domestic  market  by  subsidiary  companies  of 
the  United  States  Steel  Corporation.^  These  index  numbers  have  been  built 
from  different  combinations  of  mill-net  yields — the  combinations  being  adapted 
to  the  type  of  analysis  for  which  each  was  designed.  The  first  section  of  the 
memorandum  is  devoted  to  a  general  description  of  the  methods  used  in  con- 
structing the  indexes  and  the  reasons  for  their  preparation.  In  the  appendix 
material,  the  handling  of  special  problems  which  arose  during  the  computations 
is  discussed  and  technical  procedures  are  outlined. 

'  The  mill-net  yield  is  the  amount  of  money  actually  received  by  the  steel  company  for  its  products, 
i.  e.,  the  delivered  price  minus  the  freight.  v 

»  Excluding  in  most  instances  shipments  of  the  Columbia  Steel  Company. 


14102 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  TOWBR 


The  Indexes 

In  the  following  paragraphs  the  indexes  which  have  been  constructed  are 
described  briefly. 

1.  GENERAL    YEARLY    INDEXES 

The  over-all  yearly  index  was  based  upon  mill-net  yields  for  nearly  all  the 
major  steel  products  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries.  These 
major  products  were  then  divided  into  two  sub-groups — light  and  heavy  * — and 
a  separate  index  was  computed  from  yields  for  products  in  each  group.  Each 
of  these  three  yearly  indexes  was  computed  by  two  somewhat  different  methods.* 
As  a  result,  six  separate  yearly  indexes  were  prepared  which  were  based  on  yield 
data  from  all  the  major  steel  producing  subsidiaries.     They  are  shown  in  Table  1. 

2.  GENERAL  MONTHLY   INDEXES 

Three  indexes  were  computed  on  a  monthly  basis:  (a)  AU  products;  (b)  Heavy 
products;  (c)  Light  products.  These  indexes  are  shown  in  Tables  2,  3,  and  4. 
The  group  of  indexes  referred  to  here  and  in  paragraph  1  above  might  be  said  to 
represent  United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries'  mill-net  yields  in  general. 
To  the  extent  that  fluctuations  in  mill-net  yields  are  representative  of  fluctuations 
in  delivered  prices,  these  yield  series  indicate  changes  in^rices. 

3.  IRON   AOE   INDEX 

In  Table  5  the  Iron  Age  composite  price  of  finished  steel  has  been  reduced  to 
index  form  for  purposes  of  comparison. 

Table  1. — Comparison  of  Annual  Mill-Net  Yield  Indexes  for  Mills  of  United  States 
Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries  Computed  from  Yields  at  Separate  Mills  and  Com- 
puted from  Average  Yields  at  All  Mills,  1920-1938 

[1926=100] 


All  Products 

Heavy  Products 

Light  Products 

Year 

Based  on 

yields  at 

separate 

miUs 

Based  on 
average 

yields  for 
all  mills 

Based  on 

yields  at 

separate 

mills 

Based  on 
average 

yields  for 
all  mills 

Based  on 

yields  at 

separate 

mills 

Based  on 
average 

yields  for 
all  mills 

1920 

125.4 
107.9 
86.0 
102.7 
108.1 
101.1 
100.0 
96.5 
93.6 
94.9 

8210 
79.4 
77.2 
89.5 
91.2 
89.1 
98.8 
».8 

124.8 
107.4 
85.7 
101.9 
107.9 
10L2 
100.0 
96.4 
93.2 
94.4 
87.8 
8L2 
78.8 
76.6 
89.0 
90.8 

99!  6 
99.7 

123.6 
105.8 
82.6 
102.6 
108.4 
101.1 
100.0 
97.1 
95.0 
96.4 
89.2 
82.8 
81.5 
80.7 
90.0 
92.2 
90.2 
101.1 
102.2 

122.7 
105.2 
82.2 
10L6 
108.2 
101.3 
100.0 
96.9 
94.3 
95.9 
88.7 
82.0 
80.8 
80.0 
89.6 
9L8 
89.6 
103.0 
103.6 

129.2 
112.2 
92.9 
102.9 
107.6 
101.1 
100.0 
95.7 
91.9 
93.1 
87.3 
81.1 
76.9 
72.8 
88.8 
90.1 
87.9 
96.0 
96.9 

129.2 

1921 

112.2 

1922 

92.9 

1923 

102.9 

1924 

107.5 

1925 

101.1 

1926 

100.0 

1927 

95.8 

92.1 

1929...          .                  

92.8 

1930 

86.8 

1931 

80.5 

1932 

76.3 

1933 

72.7 

1934 

88.6 

1935 

89.7 

1936 

87.3 

1037 

95.4 

1938 

95.3 

Source:  All  indexes  computed  from  mill-net  yields  of  major  steel  products  shipped  I 
by  mills  of  subsidiary  companies  of  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation. 


•  The  major  products  falling  into  the  "heavy"  classification  are:  semi-flnished  goods, 
rails,  and  pipe.    "Light"  products  Include  sheet,  strip,  tin  plate,  and  wire  products. 
<  A  description  of  these  methods  appears  in  the  Appendix. 


the  domestic  market 
plates,  shapes,  bars. 


I 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  TOWER 


14103 


Table  2. — Monthly  Indexes  of  Mill-Net  Yields  for  Steel  Products  Shipped  to  the 
Domestic  Market  by  Mills  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries,  1912- 
19S9 

[Average  month  of  1926=100] 


Year 

Jan. 

Feb. 

March 

April 

May 

June 

July 

Aug. 

Sept. 

Oct. 

Nov. 

Dec. 

1912 

57.9 

57.3 

57.5 

57.6 

58.1 

68.4 

58.3 

58.9 

59.6 

60.8 

60.9 

61.9 

1913 

63.3 

64.3 

65.2 

65.7 

66.0 

66.4 

66.2 

65.9 

65.3 

64.2 

62.9 

1914 

61.2 

60.8 

61.2 

61.1 

60.6 

59.9 

59.0 

59.2 

59.4 

59.6 

69.5 

58.8 

1916 

58.2 
67.3 

58.0 
68.7 

58.1 
71.0 

58.8 
74.2 

59.1 
77.3 

59.6 
79.2 

60.1 
82.3 

60.4 
84.0 

61.0 
86.0 

62.1 

63.1 
90.8 

64.5 

1916 

93.6 

1917 

98.8 

103.5 

107.3 

111.9 

115.4 

118.7 

123.3 

127.5 

131.5 

134.4 

134.2 

132.8 

1918 

139.3 

137.6 

136.1 

135.8 

137.9 

138.2 

139.4 

139.6 

140.6 

142.1 

142.6 

140.2 

1919 

136.1 

134.7 

132.1 

125.4 

123.9 

122.0 

121.9 

121.5 

121.2 

121.5 

120.8 

121.6 

1920.. 

122.2 

122.2 

122.3 

123.5 

124.0 

123.8 

124.4 

124.8 

125.1 

126.1 

125.8 

126.6 

1921 

126.1 
85.4 

126.5 
84.7 

126.6 
82.8 

118.7 
82.7 

114.6 
82.9 

113.6 
83.6 

106.1 
84.2 

98.7 
85.1 

94.6 
86.2 

90.4 
87.3 

86.9 

1922 

90.0 

1923 

91.9 
112.6 
101.9 

94.1 
112.7 
102.3 

96.0 
113.0 
102.9 

98.4 
112.6 
103.0 

100. 4 
111.0 
102.3 

101.9 
108.3 
100.7 

103.6 
107.3 
100.2 

105.1 
105.3 
100.3 

106.2 
104.2 
99.7 

107.7 
102.0 
99.7 

110.4 
101.4 
99.6 

110.6 

1924 

101.2 

1925 

99.6 

1926 

99.8 

100.0 

99.6 

100.2 

100.1 

99.8 

99.8 

99.5 

99.9 

99.6 

99.9 

99.8 

1927 

98.7 

98.0 

97.0 

96.6 

95  9 

96.4 

96.3 

96.3 

95.9 

94.9 

95.2 

93.5 

1928 

93.4 

93.4 

93.3 

93.4 

94.3 

93.8 

92.9 

92.4 

92.7 

92.9 

93.9 

93.7 

1929 

94.2 

94.2 

93.9 

94.3 

94.2 

94.3 

95.0 

96.4 

94.6 

94  3 

94.3 

94.0 

1930 

92.4 

91.6 

91.2 

89.9 

88.9 

88.0 

86.6 

86.0 

85.0 

83.3 

82.0 

1931 

82.2 

83.2 

82.3 

81.8 

81.4 

80.4 

79.9 

79.8 

81.9 

80.0 

81.3 

80.2 

1932 

78.6 
77.0 

79.1 
76.0 

79.3 
76.6 

78.7 
75.0 

77.7 
74.5 

79.2 
74.6 

79.5 
73.6 

79.3 
76.0 

79.0 

77.2 

78.8 
79.4 

78.2 
82.6 

77.9 

1933 

83.6 

1934 

87.1 

88.1 

87.4 

87.1 

87.4 

91.8 

92.9 

91  9 

93  3 

92.5 

89.9 

1935 

92.1 

92.0 

91.9 

91.9 

92.0 

91.2 

90.5 

90.8 

90.0 

89.6 

88.8 

89.6 

1936 

89.0 

89.1 

87.6 

86.4 

87.1 

88.2 

87.3 

88.8 

89.6 

90.0 

90.6 

1937.. 

91.4 

92.3 

93.3 

95.8 

98.0 

99.8 

101.6 

101.9 

103.4 

105.7 

104.8 

105.3 

1938 

105.4 
93.2 

105.1 
94.1 

105.9 
95.8 

104.3 
95.1 

104.4 
94.8 

102.7 
92.1 

97.9 
91.4 

96.2 

95.9 

93.7 

91.6 

92.2 

1939 

Source:  Computed  from  mill-net  yields  for  the  major  steel  products  shipped  to  the  domestic  market  by 
mills  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries.  Complete  notes  are  presented  In  the  text  of  the 
memorandum. 


Table  3. — Monthly  Indexes  of  Mill-Net  Yields  for  Heavy  Steel  Products  Shipped 
to  the  Domestic  Market  by  Mills  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries, 
1912-19S9 

[Average  month  of  1926=100] 


Year 

Jan. 

Feb. 

March 

April 

May 

June 

July 

Aug. 

Sept. 

Oct. 

Nov. 

Dec. 

1912 

58.2 
64.1 

67.5 
65.1 

57.6 
66.0 

67.7 
60  1 

58.2 
67.0 

58.9 
67.1 

58.6 
66.9 

59.3 
67.1 

60.3 
67.2 

61.6 
66.6 

61.7 
65.5 

62.7 

1913 

63.8 

1914 

62.2 

61.8 

62.3 

61.6 

60.9 

60.3 

59.6 

59.9 

59.8 

59.7 

59.6 

59.1 

1915 

69.0 

58.4 

58. 3 

58.8 

00.2 

59.6 

60.0 

60.3 

60.9 

62.6 

63.8 

65.3 

1916 

68.5 

69.6 

71.8 

75.1 

78.4 

80.6 

84.0 

85.4 

87.9 

90.1 

93.0 

96.4 

1917 

102.0 

105.1 

109.3 

114.4 

118.3 

120.6 

124.0 

128.4 

132.9 

134.9 

134.9 

136.3 

1918 

140.1 

137.5 

135.0 

137.3 

138.1 

i.''7. 8 

140.2 

140.9 

140.3 

141.8 

141.2 

141.0 

1919 

137.4 

136.9 

132.5 

125.3 

122.8 

l.iO.  7 

120.6 

119.7 

119.0 

118.4 

117.7 

119.0 

1920 

120.8 

121.1 

120.6 

121.4 

122.0 

121.8 

122.0 

122.7 

122.8 

123.6 

123.3 

123.2 

1921..... 

123.1 

123.5 

123.8 

114.6 

111.4 

110.7 

104.7 

97.0 

93.1 

87.9 

85.3 

83.0 

1922 

81.6 

81.3 

78. 9 

78.9 

79.0 

79.5 

80.5 

81.3 

82.4 

84.7 

85.9 

87.5 

1923 

112!  9 

92.6 
113.5 

95.1 
114.1 

113^6 

100.8 
111.9 

102.6 
108.8 

104.0 
107.8 

105.1 
105.8 

106.1 
104.6 

107.5 
101.7 

109.7 
100.7 

110.7 

1924 

100.1 

1925... 

101.7 

102.1 

102.3 

102.6 

102.3 

101.1 

100.8 

101.2 

100.5 

100.4 

100.0 

100.2 

1926. 

99.9 

99.6 

99.2 

99.8 

99.7 

99.8 

100.4 

100.6 

100.4 

100.2 

100.3 

99.3 

1927 

-99.3 

99.4 

98.5 

97.7 

97.3 

97.3 

96.7 

96.4 

95.3 

93.5 

93.9 

92.4 

1928 

93  9 

94.1 

93.6 

94.4 

95.5 

9.'.0 

93.7 

93.5 

93.8 

94.1 

95.3 

95.0 

1929 

96.9 

95.9 

94.8 

96.6 

95.3 

95.5 

96.2 

97.2 

95.8 

96.0 

95.6 

94.7 

1930 

94.9 

94.3 

93.4 

91.0 

90.5 

86.8 

85.9 

84.9 

83.7 

83.4 

82.3 

1931 

83.3 

84.4 

83.3 

82.9 

82.3 

80.8 

80.2 

80.5 

82.0 

80.1 

81.9 

79.9 

1932 

79.1 

80.8 

80.8 

81.1 

79.3 

81.0 

81.6 

81.9 

81.2 

81.9 

81.5 

81.1 

1933 

80.8 

79.8 

80.3 

78.6 

77.9 

78.1 

76.1 

•'3.0 

81.4 

83.4 

85.4 

85.8- 

1934 

86.6 

87.7 

86.4 

89.2 

92.4 

94.1 

9,3..? 

94.3 

94.0 

91.3 

1935 

93.2 

93  3 

93.0 

93.0 

93.3 

92.3 

91.8 

91.7 

90.9 

90.3 

91.1 

1936 

90.1 

90.9 

90.1 

87.5 

87.2 

89.7 

87.9 

88.6 

89.9 

90.5 

90.9 

92.1 

1937 

93.4 

63.9 

94.8 

97.9 

99.9 

101.5 

103.9 

104.7 

106.2 

108.0 

106.9 

106.9 

1938 

107.1 

107.1 

109.0 

106.6 

106.0 

104.5 

99.4 

97.9 

97.4 

95.7 

96.0 

95.6 

1939 

95.1 

96.7 

97.5 

95.5 

96.7 

94.9 

93.7 

Source:  Comr 

Uted  fn 

)m  mill 

net  yiel 

(Is  forth 

e  major 

heavy s 

teel  pro 

lucts  sh 

ippedt 

)  the  do 

mestic  n 

aarket 

by  mills  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries.    Complete  notes  are  presented  in  the  text  of  this 
memorandum. 


14104 


CONCENTRATION  OF  T<X)ONOMIC  POWER 


Table  4.— Monthly  Indexes  of  Mill-Net  Yields  for  Light  Steel  Products  Shipped  to 
the  Domestic  Market  by  Mills  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  Subsidiaries, 
1912-19S9 

[Average  month  of  1926  =  100) 


Year 


Jan. 


Feb.    March   April     May 


June 


July 


Aug. 


Sept. 


Oct. 


Nov. 


Dec. 


1912. 
1913. 
1914. 
1915. 
1916. 
1917. 
1918- 
1919. 
1920. 
1921. 
1922. 
1923. 
1924. 
1925. 

1927^ 
1928. 
1929. 
1930. 
1931. 
1932. 
1933. 
1934. 
1935- 


57.9 
62.1 
59.8 
57.3 


138.6 
134.7 
125.7 
132.7 

112!  5 
103.1 
100.2 
98.0 
92.8 
92.4 
89.4 
80.9 
78.1 
72.4 
87.7 
91.1 
87.8 
89.3 
103.5 
91.0 


57.3 
07.5 
101.4 
138.7 
133.2 
125.0 
133.2 
92.1 
97.6 
111.7 
103»5 
101.5 
96.4 
92.5 
92.2 

8l!7 
77.1 
71.6 
87.8 
00.7 
87.1 
90.5 
102.9 
91.0 


57.9 
64.1 
59.6 
57.9 
07.8 
104.3 
139.0 
132.2 
126.5 
133.0 
91.1 
98.5 
111.3 
104.8 
101.1 
95.2 
93.1 
92.8 
88.8 
81.2 
77.5 
72.3 
87.2 
90.8 
84.7 
91.4 
102.4 
93.9 


73.1 
107.6 
138.8 
126.6 
128.2 
127.9 


111.0 
194.5 
101.6 
95.5 
92.2 
92.9 


75.7 
70.6 
88.1 
90.7 
85.2 
93.2 
101.7 
94.8 


68.2 
64.7 
60.1 
59.2 
75.9 
110.0 
138.6 
126.8 
128.8 
121.9 
91.3 
100.4 


92.9 
87.1 
80.5 
75.9 
70.6 
87.8 
90.7 
87.1 
95.8 
102.6 
92.7 


.';7.9 
65.2 
59.5 
00.0 
77.0 
115.7 
140.0 
125.0 
128.5 
120.2 
92.1 
101.1 
108.0 
100.5 
100.3 
95.3 
92.5 
93.1 
86.8 
80.0 
77.1 
70.3 
86.5 
90.1 
86.6 
98.0 
100.8 
88.8 


58.4 
65.3 
58.3 
60.5 
79.8 
122.5 


92.2 
103.3 
106.7 
99.3 
99.3 
95.9 
92.0 
93.5 
86.5 
79.8 
77.1 
70.2 
91.2 
89.3 
86.9 
98.9 
96.2 
88.7 


58.6 
64.5 
58.3 
60.9 
81.8 
126.6 
137.6 
125.7 
129.9 
102,7 


105.0 
99.0 
98.2 
96.2 
91.1 
93.4 
86.3 
79.2 
76.1 
71.5 
91.5 
89.8 
87.8 
98.7 
94.3 


59.0 
63.8 
59.1 
61.3 
83.1 
129.8 
142.2 
120.2 
130.5 
98.1 
94.2 
107.0 
104.0 
98.8 
99.3 
96.9 
91.5 
93.1 
85.2 
81.8 
76.5 
72.0' 
90.4 

87^8 
100.1 
94.2- 


61.5 
85. 1 
134,5 
143,8 
128.5 
132.0 
96.2 
93.3 
108.6 
103.4 
99,0 
99.0 
96.8 
91.6 
92.5 


75.0 
74,6 
92.1 
88.7 
.88,5 
103.0 
91.4 


59.8 
62.2 
59.7 
62.0 
87.2 
133.8 
146,2 
127,6 
131.5 
94.3 
94.5 
112.4 
103.3 
99.0 
99.6 
96.9 
92.1 
92.9 
83.2 
80.8 
74.4 
79.3 
90.7 
88.3 

102!  4 
86.3 


127.1 
139.4 
127.4 
133.6 
95.0 
95.6 
111.2 
103.7 
99.3 
100.7 
95.1 
.92.3 
93.3 
81.9 
80.6 
74.1 
80.8 

87^7 

103^5 
88.3 


'  Source:  Computed  from  mill-net  yields  for  the  major  light  steel  products  sTiipped  to  the  domestic  market 
by  mills  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries.  Complete  notes  are  presented  in  the  text  of  this 
memorandum. 


Table  5.- 


■The  Iron  Age  Composite  Price  of  Finished  Steel  as  an  Index,  1912-1989 
[Average  month  of  1926=100] 


Feb.    March   April     May     June      July      Aug.     Sept.      Oct, 


1912. 
1913. 
1914. 
1915. 
1916. 
1917. 
1918. 
1919- 
1920. 
1921. 
1922. 
1923. 
1924. 
1925. 
1926. 
1927. 
1928. 
1929. 
1930. 


1932. 
1933. 
1934. 
1935. 
1936. 
1937. 


61.5 
76.5 
62.7 

14612 
153.3 
145.6 
162.7 
129.1 
84.6 
103.7 
118,6 
104,1 
100,3 
98.5 
92.3 
94,7 
93,4 
85.4 
81.2 
81.4 
84.0 


97.1 
lOS.  5 
98.7 


95.2 
151.2 
153.3 
145.6 
152.7 
123.1 
82.2 
109.5 
117.5 
104.6 
100.0 
95.9 
93.7 
94.7 
92.8 
85.6 


97.1 
108.5 
98.7 


60.2 

77.1 
63,6 
61,0 
105,7 
161,5 
153,3 
141,8 
164.2 
115,9 
82,2 
115,5 
115.0 
104.7 
100.3 
86.5 
94.1 
94.7 
92.7 


61.9 
77.3 
62.5 
62,1 
112,8 
177.5 
153,3 
130,9 
170,9 
114,0 
85,1 
119,9 
112,0 
102,0 
100,1 
96.2 
94.0 
96.0 
90.6 
85,3 
82.4 
78.5 
85.9 


74.6 
61.5 
61.9 
118.8 
197.1 
153,3 
130,5 
168,0 
114,5 
87.7 
119,7 
100.2 
100.6 
99.5 
95.7 
93.0 
96.2 

9,b.'i 
82.4 


62.4 
116.2 
216.2 
153.3 
130.5 
166.3 
109.0 

90.1 
118.6 
108.0 


95.5 
93.0 
96.6 


82.4 
78.6 
91.5 


65.0 
72.0 
60.5 
63.5 
114.0 


102.2 
91,5 
118,6 
105.8 


87.2 
84.4 
82.7 
81.1 

90I3 
108.5 
39,4 
96.6 


67.1 
70,2 
62,5 
65,3 
115,9 
226.7 
153,3 
130.5 
172.7 
96.0 
87.0 
118.6 
103.5 


100.0 
95.4 
93.3 
95,6 
86,3 
84,0 
82.7 


90.3 
108.5 
99.4 


69.5 
68.7 
63.5 
67.3 
119,4 
218,1 
153,3 
129,8 
170,8 
93,0 
101,6 
118.6 
101.8 
97.7 
100.0 
95,0 
93.3 
95.4 
85,9 
84,0 
82,7 
81,6 


90.5 
108.5 
99.0 


71.7 
67.3 
62.5 
70.6 
123.4 
149.8 
153,3 
131.8 
162.5 
91.3 
103.6 
118.6 
101.0 
98.3 
100.0 

93,7 
94.9 
85.6 
84.0 


89.1 
91.4 
108.5 
97.4 


73.4 
65.0 
60.3 
76.4 
130.5 
148.8 
153.3 
133,2 
154.2 
88.8 
103,3 
118.6 
101.6 
99.8 
100.0 
92.1 
94.2 


74.5 
63.2 
59.0 
83.8 
141.6 
148.6 
149,5 
134,3 
133.1 
86.4 
102.4 
118.0 
103.6 
100.6 
100.0 
92.1 
94.5 
95.2 
84.8 
82.5 
82,0 
84,0 


89,1 
95.0 
108.5 
98.7 


Source:  Computed  from  data  published  in  the/ron  Age,  January 
in  the  weekly  issues  through  August,  1939. 


1939,  p.  199,  and  from  data  published 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  TOWER  14105 

General  Statistical  Methods 

At  this  stage  it  is  in  point  to  discuss  the  reasons  for  reducing  mill-net  yield  data 
to  index  number  form  and  also  the  methods  by  which  this  may  be  accomplished. 

An  index  number  may  be  defined  as  a  device  for  summarizing  the  fluctuations  of 
a  number  of  individual  groups  or  series  of  figures.  The  need  for  such  a  summary  is 
indicated  in  the  following  discussion.  Although  mill-net  yields  from  the  sale  of 
steel  plates,  to  take  an  example  at  random,  are  important  among  yields  for  steel 
products,  the  fluctuations  in  yields  for  steel  plates  could  not  safely  be  assumed  to 
-be  indicative  of  the  changes  in  mill-net  yields  fgr  steel  products  in  general.  The 
same  thing  may  be  said  of  the  yields  for  any  other  single  steel  product.  Clearly, 
some  kind  of  summarization  is  necessary  because  a  single  yield  series  is  not  suffi- 
ciently comprehensive  to  be  representative  of  a  broad  classification  of  goods. 
Therefore,  in  order  to  have  some  way  of  measuring  the  relative  changes  in  steel 
mill-net  yields  in  general,  it  is  necessary  to  analyze  either  all  the  individual  mill- 
net  yields  for  all  steel  products,  i.  e.,  plates,  structural  shapes,  rails,  sheets,  tin 
plate,  etc.,  or,  at  least,  the  mill-net  yields  for  a  representative  sample  of  all  steel 
products.  But  if  each  of  the  many  groups  of  yields  were  to  be  considered  singly, 
it  would  be  impossible  to  arrive  at  any  definite  conclusions  about  their  movements 
taken  as  a  whole.  Therefore,  such  groups  of  figures  or  series  are  often  combined  or 
averaged  into  a  single  series  of  figujes  so  as  to  obtain  a  composite,  month  by 
month  or  year  by  yeat,  as  the  case  may  be,  of  their  movements  as  a  group. 

This  combined  or  average  series  of  figures  is  the  basis  for  an  index  nuhaber. 
Since  the  actual  numerical  value  of  any  item  in  a  combined  series  has  little  or  no 
meaning  in  itself,  the  members  of  that  series  are  usually  expressed  as  relatives. 
That  is,  one  item  of  the  combined  series,  or  an  average  of  several,  is  selected  as  a 
base,gfid  its  relative  is  said  to  be  equal  to  100;  then  the  other  members  of  the  series 
are  expressed  as  a  percent  of  the  base.  When  the  same  base  is  used  for  an  entire 
series,  the  series  is  said  to  have  been  related  to  a  fixed  base. 

Clearly,  the  mill-net  yields  of  individual  products  difi'er  in  importance  depending 
upon  such  criteria  as  the  amounts  of  the  different  kinds  of  products  usually  shipped 
or  upon  their  value.  In  averaging  the  yields  used  in  an  index,  therefore,  it  is 
necessary  that  each  figure -be  multiplied  by  an  appropriate  weighting  factor,  for 
in  that  way  the  relative  effect  of  the  movements  of  any  one  of  the  component 
.series  is  limited  to  a  predetermined  proportion  of  the  whole. . 

Index  numbers  are  ordinarily  described  by  the  method  used  in  making  the 
combinations.  The  actual  methods  of  construction  are  various,  depending  on 
the  kind  of  average  used  and  the  way  in  which  the  magnitude  of  group  change 
is  expressed.  All  of  the  mill-net  yield  indexes  of  which  the  construction  is 
described  in  this  memorandum  are  of  the  general  type  known  as  ratios  of  aggre- 
gates. This  means  that  the  index  number  for  any  month  or  year  was  obtained 
by  computing  the  sum  of  the  products  '  of  individual  mill-net  yields  and  the 
corresponding  selected  weighting  factors.  The  result  of  this  process,  called  an 
aggregate,  was  then  divided  by  a  similar  aggregate  for  the  selected  base  period 
in  order  to  express  the  aggregate  as  a  relative.^ 

It  is  usually  undesirable  to  use  the  same  set  of  weights  throughout  a  long 
period.  With  the  passing  of  time,  certain  products  become  less  important  and 
others  more  important.  Extreme  cases  of  this  kind  occur  whenever  a  product 
ceases  to  be  produced  or  a  new  one  is  marketed  and  becomes  important.  Further- 
more, allowances  must  be  made  for  changes  in  the  form  in  which  the  data  are 
reported.  Most  of  these  difficulties  can  be  overcome  by  using  several  weighting 
periods  and  then  chaining  the  aggregates  for  these  periods, into  a  single  series. 
A  weighting  period  is  simply  a  group  of  years  or  months  for  which  the  same  set 
of  weights  is  used  in  computing  the  aggregates.  A  different  group  of  weights  is 
determined  for  each  weighting  period.  Then,  in  order  to  make  a  continuous 
series,  the  aggregates  for  each  weighting  period  are  chained  together.  Chaining 
is  accomplished  by  computing  aggregates  for  one  overlapping  month  or  year. 
That  is,  if  July,  1926,  were  selected  as  the  point  for  chaining,  an  aggregate  for 
July  would  be  computed  as  of  the  original  weighting  period  and  another  aggregate 
as  of  the  second  one.     The  original  series  could  then  be  extended  by  computing 

1  The  word  "product"  is  used  here  in  the  mathematical  sense.    If  Yi,  Yj,  Y3,  etc.,  are  yields  for  a  series 
of  products  and  Wi,  W2,  Wj,  etc.,  are  their  respective  weighting  factors,,  the  sum  of  the  paired  products 
would  be  Yi,  multiplied  by  Wi.  plus  Yj  multiplied  by  Wj,  plus  (Y3W3),  etc. 
»  The  mathematical  formula  for  this  index  is: 

S  (WkYi) 
2  (WkYo) 

in  which  Wk  is  the  weighting  factor,  Yo  the  mill-net  yield  for  the  base  period,  and  Yi,  the  mill-net  yield 
for  the  given  period. 


14106  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWEfR 

the  next  item — the  figure  for  August — which  would  be  larger  or  smaller  than 
the  July  aggregate  in  the  original  series  in  the  same  proportion  that  the  August 
figure  was  larger  than  the  July  figure  in  the  second  series. 

When  it  becomes  necessary  to  break  these  series  into  weighting  periods,  the 
breaks  should  come  at  points  where  adjustments  can  be  made  for  as  many  as 
possible  of  the  changes  which  are  bound  to  creep  into  the  series.  Any  period 
may  be  used  as  a  base  for  computing  relatives  in  this  kind  of  an  index.  The 
actual  selection  of  a  particular  base  depends  on  what  period  the  maker  of  the 
index  wishes  to  emphasize  or  to  consider  as  normal.  The  base  for  anj  index 
may  be  easily  shifted  to  another  year  or  month  by  dividing  all  the  present  index 
numbers  by  the  index  number  for  the  selected  year  or  month. 

Data  From  Which  the  Indexes  Were  Computed 

1.  mill-net  yields 

The  basic  materials  for  these  indexes  were  monthly  figures  on  the  tonnages  shipped 
and  the  mill-net  selling  values  of  more  than  75  classes  of  steel  products.^  These 
tonnages  and  amounts  were  used  to  compute  average  mill-net  yields.  Roughly 
75  per  cent  of  the  total  tonnage  of  steel  shipped  each  year  by  United  States 
Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  was  covered  by  these  figures.  Reports  from  the 
Carnegie-Illinois  Steel  Corporation  and  the  National  Tube  Company  were  tabu- 
lated for  individual  mills.  The  American  Steel  and  Wire  Company,  the  American 
Sheet  and  Tin  Plate  Company,  and  the  Tennessee  Coal,  Iron  and  Railroad 
Company,  on  the  other  hand,  reported  on  a  company  basis  only.  Shipments 
of  the  Pacific  Coast  subsidiary  were  not  included  in  the  computations. 

The  classes  of  products  which  could  be  used  were  limited  by  the  form  in  which 
records  were  originally  reported  and  subsequently  kept,  on  file  by  the  subsidiary 
companies.  Since  the  use  of  all  the  yield  data  available  would  have  entailed 
a  great  amou'  it  of  clerical  labor,  only  the  most  important  products,  from  a  tonnage 
standpoint,  ;  nd  those  products  made  at  the  most  important  mills  were  used. 
Practically  £.J  aUoy  steels  have  been  excluded  from  these  figures.  Details  con- 
cerning the  use  of  the  mill-net  yield  data  in  the  indexes  are  included  in  the  Ap- 
pendix, 

2.  DATA    USED   IN    PREPARING   WEIGHTS 

All  of  the  weights  were  based  on  tonnage  figures  reported  in  the  United  States 
Steel  Corporation's  "Annual  Summaries  of  Domestic  Shipments"  in  which  the 
total  tonnages  of  the  various  steel  products  shipped  to  the  domestic  market  by 
all  United  States  Steel  Corporation  subsidiaries  are  shown.  The  classes  of 
products  reported  therein  differ  in  several  respects  from  the  classes  of  pi'oducts 
by  which  the  monthly  mill-net  yield  data  were  reported.  In  the  "Annual  Sum- 
maries of  Domestic  Shipments,"  all  steel  products  are  accounted  for,  but  the 
actual  product  classes  which  are  used  vary  considerably  from  year  to  year. 
Although  more  kinds  of  products  are  represented  in  the  annual  summaries,  the 
monthly  data  were  usually  reported  only  for  certain  important  subclassifications, 
the  makeup  of  which  tended  to  be  relatively  homogeneous.  The  mechanics 
involved  in  computing  the  weights  used  in  the  mill-net  yield  indexes  are  described 
in  the.  Appendix. 

Appendix 

Notes  and  explanations  relating  to  special  statistical  procedures  or  problems 
involved  in  the  construction  of  the  indexes  are  presented  in  this  section  of  the 
report. 

WEIGHT   computations 

Although  the  products  for  which  mill-net  yields  were  available  represent  only 
part  of  the  tonnage  actually  shipped,  the  weights  used  in  constructing  the  indexes 
were  related  to  almost  all  of  the  products  shipped.  That  is,  the  weights  were  based 
not  only  upon  the  tonnage  shipped  of  the  particular  products  for  which  mill-net 
yields  were  available,  but  also  upon  the  tonnages  of  the  other  products  for  which 
yields  were  not  available  in  detail.  The  reason  for  using  all  these  products  in  the 
weighting  computations  is  that  it  is  desirable  to  give  a  single  component  series  as 
much  weight  as  it  deserves  from  a_  proportional  view  point.  Therefore,  if  the 
movements  of  a  given  series  are  not  only  representative  of  the  particular  product, 
but  are  also  reasonably  representative  of  the  movements  of  another  series,  it  may 
be  used  to  represent  the  second  series  in  instances  where  no  yields  are  obtainable. 

«  Data  for  the  76  product  classes  were  not,  however,  all  available  at  any  one  time. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       14107 

Furthermore,  it  should  be  noted  that  the  more  homogeneous  are  the  products 
included  in  a  single  series,  the  more  likely  it  is  that  the  fluctuations  in  the  miU-net 
yields  are  genuine  and  do  not  result  in  part  from  varying  quantities  of  subclassifi- 
cations  of  goods  of  different  qualities. 

Several  methods  were  used' to  determine  what  products  might  be  most  suitably 
included  in  a  single  weight  group.  The  yearly  movements  of  the  series  for  which 
mill-net  yields  were  reported  in  the  annual  shipment  summaries  were  compared 
with  each  other  in  some  instances.  Whenever  the  movements  of  several  series 
were  found  to  be  similar,  shipments  of  these  products  were  combined  for  weighting 
purposes.  In  other  cases,  knowledge  of  the  product  or  the  way  it  was  customarily 
priced  determined  into  what  weighting  group  its  influence  should  be  thrown. 

BELECTION    OF    WEIGHTING   PERIODS 

The  yearly  indexes  prepared  in  this  study  were  chained  at  1926,  and  1936,  so 
that  three  weighting  periods  were  used  1920-1926,  1926-1936,  193&-1938.  The 
weighting  periods  used  for  the  monthly  series  were  as  follows: 

January,  1912— August,  1920 
August,  1920— July,  1926 
July,  1926— July,  1936 
July,  1936— June,  1938 
June,  1938— July,  1939 

The  monthly  series  were  chained  in  the  same  years  as  the  yearly  series  so  that 
their  periods  would  be  similar.  Before  the  actual  month  was  selected  at  which 
the  shift  was  to  be  made,  monthly  aggregates  for  both  series  were  computed.  The 
month  selected  for  chaining  in  each  case,  e.  g.,  Jul^  1926,  was  one  for  which  the 
difference  between  the  aggregates  of  the  two  series  seemed  to  be  about  tb*^  eame^as 
the  average  for  the  year. 

As  a  base  period  for  all  of  these  series  the  aggregate  for  1926,  or  for  the  average 
month  of  1926,  was  chosen  for  several  reasons.  The  year  1926  may  be  described 
as  one  of  relatively  normal  business  conditions,  i.  e.,  neither  a  boom  nor  a  depres- 
sion was  in  progress.  Mill-net  yield  levels  were  relatively  stable  throughout  the 
year.     Furthermore,  1926  is  often  used  as  the  liase  for  year  index  numbers. 

The  weights  used  for  the  period  1912-1920  inclusive  were  computed  on  the  ba^is 
of  shipments  during  the  year  1920.  Weights  for  the  other  periods  were  based  on 
average  shipments  for  several  years.  For  the  period  1920-1926  the  weights  were 
based  on  1924,  1925,  and  1926  shipments,  and  those  from  1926  through  1936  on 
average  shipments  for  1934,  1935,  1936,  and  1937.  Redistribution  of  the  latter 
weights  to  different  product  classes  were  made  for  the  1936-1938  and  1938-1939 
periods. 

Weights  for  the  1926-1936  period  were  based  on  shipments  in  the  years  at  the 
end  of  the  veighting  period  so  that  the  index  would  be  weighted  by  a  combination 
of  products  typical  of  recent  years.'  The  same  principle  was  applied  to  the  1920- 
1926  weights.  The  years  1924-1926  and  1934-1937  were  averaged  in  each  case 
so  that  the  weights  would  not  be  greatly  influenced  by  variations  in  shipments 
caused  by  cyclical  changes  in  the  volume  of  business.  The  selection  of  1920  ship- 
ments for  the  purpose  of  weighting  the  1912-1920  period  was  in  accordance  with 
these  procedures.  The  break  was  made  in  the  series  in  1936  because  so  many 
new  product  classifications  became  available  at  about  that  time.  It  seemed,  how- 
ever, when  it  came  to  constructing  weights  for  the  1936-1938  or  1938-1939  periods 
that  the  weights  computed  on  the  basis  of  1934-1937  shipments  could  not  be  im- 
proved upon.  Therefore,  the  weights  for  product  groups  derived  from  shir^ments 
for  1934,  1935,  1936,  and  1937  were  merely  redistributed  to  the  larger  nudiber  of 
classifications  available  in  the  years  1936-1938.  In  order  to  use  data  for  1939,  it 
was  necessary  to  shift  the  weights  again  because  of  the  change  in  the  form  in  which 
the  data  were  reported. 

COMPUTATION  OF  TWO  GENERAL  INDEXEt 

In  an  early  section  of  this  memorandum  it  was  noted  that  the  general  yearly 
indexes  had  been  computed  by  two  slightly  different  processes.  A  description 
of  the  methods  and  reasons  for  their  use  follows: 


'  Weighting  by  quantities  sold  in  years  near  the  end  of  each  weighting  period  probably  results  in  a  slightly 
lower  index  than  weighting  by  quantities  sold  in  years  near,  the  beginning  of  each  weighting  period.  This 
small  downward  bias  tends  to  offset  the  small  upward  bias  Inherent  in  some  of  the  mill-net  series  due  to  the 
gradual  introduction  and  growth  of  higher  priced  specialty  steels  In  some  of  the  classes  of  products.  This 
upward  bias  was  kept  ^  low  as  possible  by  using  only  standard  products  and  excluding  specialty  producti 
from  the  series  used  in  the  index. 

124491- 41— pt.  26 34 


14108  CONCENTRATION  OF  BOONORIIC  POWRR 

In  computing  the  first  general  yearly  index,  separate  mill-net  yields  were  used 
for  each  product  at  each  mill  in  so  far  as  the  data  were  available  in  that  form. 
For  the  products  which  were  reported  only  on  a  company  basis,  the  average  mill- 
net  yield  for  the  company  as  a  whole  had  to  be  used.  The  weight  arrived  at  for 
each  product  was  allocated  among  the  mills  according  to  the  importance  of  each 
miU. 

Theoretically,  the  same  plan  could  have  been  used  in  the  computation  of  the 
monthly  indexes,  but  some  practical  difficulties  interfered.  In  the  first  place, 
some  of  the  monthly  series  were  incomplete,  i.  e.,  occasionally  no  public  shipments 
were  made  during  a  month  or  series  of  months.  Such  lapses  in  the  data  were 
naturally  frequent  among  products  which  are  primarily  shipped  to  oth6r  plants 
of  the  company  for  further  finishing.  Also,  plants  would  occasionally  be  shut 
down  for  repair.  Gaps  in  the  series  could  not  be  ignored  in  the  proces.s  of  comput- 
ing the  index  because  the  effect  of  the  omission  of  the  amount  represented  by  the 
mill-net  yield  multiplied  by  the  appropriate  weight  would  usually  be  sufficient 
to  cause  an  unreal  movement  in  the  final  index.  If  such  breaks  in  the  data  were 
relatively  infrequent,  it  was  usually  possible  to  substitute  a  reasonable  figure  in  the 
blank,  but  when  the  number  of  months  in  which  no  shipments  occurred  became 
frequent,  there  was  less  justification  for  substitution  and  the  computation  pro- 
cedure had  to  be  altered. 

At  the  same  time,  another  difficulty  arose  with  respect  to  the  mill-net  yield 
data.  So  far  as  it  was  possible,  the  individual  series  were  confined  to  homogeneous 
product  groupings,  but  in  the  case  of  steel  product  groups  homogeneity  is  only  a 
relative  term.  Each  separate  shipment,  even  though  nominally  related  to  the 
same  base  price,  is  subject  to  different  additions  and  deductions.  When  the  total 
shipments  for  any  month  are  very  small,  the  yield  for  these  shipments  will  not 
always  be  representative  of  the  average  either  for  that  mill  or  that  general  class  of 
prv,ducts.  A  substantial  variation  in  the  yield  for  one  month  brought  about  by 
a  small  tonnage  shipped  at  an  abnormally  high  or  low  yield  can,  therefore,  cause 
unwarranted  variations  in  the  index. 

Because  of  these  two  major  difficulties  which  arise  from  the  use  of  the  monthly 
data  at  separate  mills,  it  seemed  advisable  to  combine  the  tonnage  figures  and  the 
selling  values  at  all  the  mills  for  each  product  and  then  compute  the  average 
mill-net  yeild  for  each  product.  The  monthly  indexes  from  1920  on  were  com- 
puted fr^m  average  mill-net  yields  for  all  reporting  mills. 

The  general  yearly  indexes  were  Qomputed  by  both  of  the  methods  just  described. 
A  comparison  of  the  indexes  computed  .by  these  methods  reveals  relatively  insig- 
nificant differences  (see  Table  1). 

THE  1912-1920  MONTHLY  INDEXES 

The  segments  of  the  monthly  indexes  covering  the  period  January,  1912,  to 
August,  1920,  were  computed  by  a  modified  procedure.  The  statistical  methods 
employed  were  identical  with  those  throughout  the  rest  of  the  series,  but 
the  data  on  which  the  computations  were  based  were  for  selected  products  and 
selected  mills.  Tiiat  is,  mill-net  yields  for  an  abbreviated  list  of  representative 
products  were  weighted  on  the  basis  of  total  shipments  for  the  year  1920.  Dis- 
cussion with  respect  to  combinations  of  data  for  groups  of  products  or  groups  of 
mills  is  not  applicable,  of  course,  to  the  1912-1920  figures. 

ADJUSTMENTS  OF  PRODUCT  CLASSIFICATIONS 

A  further  adjustment  had  to  be  made  in  some  of  the  miU-net  yields  in  order  to 
make  the  data  comparable.  As  it  has  been  stated  previously,  even  a  relatively 
homogeneous  product  classification  may  be  composed  of  sub-groups  of  products 
some  of  which  could  reasonably  be  reported  separately.  The  result  of  this  situa- 
tion is  that  changes  in  product  classifications  have  often  occurred  which  did  not 
actually  involve  the  addition  or  deletion  of  a  particular  type  of  product  from  those 
shipped.  Thus  it  is,  to  use  a  specific  example,  that  the  classification  "bars, 
rounds,  etc."  for  a  number  of  years  might  include,  "deformed  concrete  bars", 
"bars,  rounds,  special  quality",  and  "seamless  tube  rounds"  in  addition  to  the 
products  usually  described  collectively  as  "bars  and  rounds."  Then  the  method 
of  reporting  shipments  would  be  changed  and  each  of  these  sub-classifications 
might  be  recorded  separately.  It  is  plain  that  after  the  separation  "bars  and 
rounds"  would  no  longer  be  the  same  class  of  products.  Therefore,  within  a  single 
weighting  period  comparability  in  the  product  class  for  "bars  and  rounds"  was 
maintained  by  combining  the  data  for  these  sub-classifications  with  the  main 
classification;  definite  splits  in  classes  wore  made  only  with  the  adoption  of  a  new 
weighting  period. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER       14109 


SUBSTITUTED  FIGURES 


Even  when  yearly  data  were  used  for  computing  index  numbers,  it  was  necessary 
in  a  few  instances  to  fill  in  a  yield  for  one  mill  in  a  blank  year.  The  usual  pro- 
cedure for  estimating  these  yields  was  to  assume  that  the  yield  in  a  given  year  at 
that  mill  would  be  related  to  the  yield  in  an  adjacent  year  in  the  same  proportion 
that  similar  yields  for  the  same  product  in  a  nearby  mill  were  related. 


The  records  of  shipments  kept  at  the  mills  contain  deductions  for  returned  goods. 
In  some  cases,  the  entire  returned  tonnage  was  subtracted  from  the  tonnage 
shipped,  but  only  part  of  the  value  of  the  returned  shipment  was  deducted. 
'Ordinarily,  the  tonnage  involved  in  irregularities  of  this  sort  would  be  relatively 
small  and  the  effect  on  the  mill-net  yield  would  consequently  be  insignificant. 
The  result  of  this  practice  in  the  case  of  coke  tin  plate,  however,  was  to  cause 
an  abnormally  high  mill-net  yield  for  December,  1938.  In  order  to  avoid  this 
variation,  a  mill-net  yield  was  computed  for  that  month  excluding  the  effect  of 
returned  goods. 

EXHIBFT  No.   2182 

IMPROVED  QUALITY  OF  STEEL  AS  A  PRICE  REDUCTION 

[This  statement  was  prepared  by  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  in  con- 
nection with  the  hearings  on  the  steel  industry  before  the  Temporary  National 
J]coDomic  Committee.] 

November  1,  1939. 

A  comparison  of  the  price  of  any  steel  product  ten  or  fifteen  years  ago  with  the 
price  of  the  product  known  by  the  same  name  today  gives  an  incomplete  and  in- 
accurate impression,  as  it  does  not  take  into  account  the  many  substantial  econ- 
omies which  buyers  of  steel  have  been  able  to  effect  by  reason  of  its  improved 
quality.  These  improvements  have  not,  in  general,  been  compensated  for  by 
price  increases,  and  have,  therefore,  amounted  to  price  reductions.  So  great 
have  these  improvements  in  quality  been,  that  in  some  cases  it  is  misleading  even 
to  call  the  products  by  the  same  name. 

Many  people  who  are  unfamiliar  with  steel  may  think  of  it  as  a  single  product, 
of  different  sizes  and  shapes,  but  of  more  or  less  uniform  quality.  This  may  have 
been  relatively  true  in  the  early  days  when  customers  had  to  adjust  their  needs 
to  the  limitations  of  steel.  Today,  however,  there  is  no  such  product  as  common 
steel,  but,  instead,  practically  aH  steel  is  "custom  made"  to  conform  to  the  special 
requirements  of  each  buyer.  The  ability  to  obtain  steel  perfectly  suited  to  their 
requirements  has  enabled  manufacturers  to  take  advantage  of  modem  methods 
of  production  to  effect  reductions  in  their  costs  and  to  design  new  models  which 
could  not  have  been  produced  with  the  steel  of  former  years. 

The  automobile  is  an  outstanding  example  of  the  custom  made  character  of 
steel.  In  the  1939  model  of  one  of  the  leading  automobiles  there  are  no  less  than 
32  distinctly  different  t5T)es  of  steel,  each  specially  made  to  order  and  designed, 
by  chemical  content  or  special  treatment,  to  meet  the  particular  requirements  of 
the  part  for  which  it  is  to  be  used.  The  steel  specifications  for  a  given  part,  for 
different  makes  of  automobiles  are  usually  different. 

Reductions  in  real  price  through  quality  improvements,  which  are  found  m 
almost  all  types  of  steel  products,  are  illustrated  by  the  following  examples  in  each 
of  the  principal  general  types  of  steel  products. 

Sheet  Steel 

The  average  base  price  of  steel  sheets  used  in  making  automobile  bodies  has 
been  reduced  approximately  30%  in  the  last  fifteen  years,  despite  the  fact  that 
duixiig  this  period  all  of  their  service  properties  have  been  tremendously  improved. 

The  modern  sheets,  made  by  a  radically  new  method  of  processing,  can  be 
produced  33j4%  thinner  and  20%  wider  than  was  possible  fifteen  years  ago  and 
can  now  be  made  in  coils  hundreds  of  feet  long  as  compared  with  a  former  maxi- 
mum length  of  100  inches.  The  deep  drawing  qualities  have  been  increased  30% 
to  40%  permitting  deeper  stamping  of  much  more  sharply  rounded  shapes.  Deep 
dr.awing   qualities,  of  common   sheets   although   limited  and   inferior  formerly 


14110  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECX)NOMIO  POWER 

entailed  an  extra  charge.     Today  there  is  no  extra  charge  for  the  truly  remarkable 
drawing  properties  of  automobile  sheets. 

The  modern  one-piece  automobile  steel  top  is  stamped  out  in  one  operation 
from  a  single  sheet  of  steel.  Formerly,  it  was  necessary  to  make  the  top  of  wood 
and  fabric  entailing  numerous  hand  operations. 

A  front  fender  can  now  be  stamped  out  of  one  sheet  in  the  same  way  in  one 
operation.  It  was  formerly  made  of  two  sheets  of  steel  separately  formed  and 
then  joined  together. 

Painting  the  surface  of  the  earlier  automobile  sheets  to  develop  an  acceptable 
finish  required  elaborate  preparation,  glazing,  and  many  separate  coats  with 
intermediate  treatment  between  each  two  coats.  Today  these  operations  are 
unnecessary,  because  of  the  fine  grain  and  dense  polished  surface  of  modem  sheet 
steel.  As  a  result,  the  time  required  to  apply  the  finish  to  a  part  has  been  reduced 
from  a  minimum  of  48  hours  to  6  hours.  The  following  photomicrographs,  (pp. 
Uin-14112)  of  a  1939  and  of  a  1924  type  of  sheet,  made  in  1939  by  1924 
methods,  show  clearly  the  improved  surface. 

Enameled  articles,  such  as  electric  refrigerators,  sinks  and  bathtubs,  made  of 
sheet  steel  are  stamped  into  shape  and  enameled.  Improvements  in  the  modern 
steel  enameling  sheets  have  permitted  the  manufacture  of  deeply  formed  modern 
designs  of  these  products,  with  a  nearly  perfect  and  non-chipping  enamel  finish 
impossible  a  few  years  ago.  Despite  these  cost  saving  improvements,  the  base 
price  of  steel  enameling  sheets  has  been  reduced  approximately  30%  in  the  last 
fifteen  years. 

The  present  day  high  quality  silicon  steel  sheets  used  in  the  electrical  industry 
have  made  possible  more  efficient  generation  and  use  of  electrical  energy  and  thus 
contribute  significantly  to  the  use  of  larger  generators  and  motors  than  were  used 
fifteen  years  ago.  The  resulting  savings  are  well  illustrated  by  reduction  in  the 
losses  of  electric  power  in  the  steel  cores  of  generators  from  .77  watts  per  pound 
in  1924  to  .52  watts  per  pound  in  1939,  an  improvement  of  about  32>^%.  These 
improved  sheets  are  sold  at  subsiantiaily  the  same  price  as  the  cprresponding 
sheets  fifteen  years  ago. 

Tin  Plate 

Approximately  50%  of  all  tin  plate  sold  today  is  so-called  "cold  reduced"  tin 
plate.  This  new  and  improved  type,  introduced  in  quantity  about  1931,  is  sold 
at  a  lowfer  price  than  the  hot  rolled  tin  plate  of  1924. 

The  improved  workability  and  resistance  to  corrosion  of  cold  reduced  tin  plate, 
which  could  not  have  been  obtained  by  1924  methods,  have  been  important  factors 
in  the  canning  industry.  Its  high  corrosion  resistance  has  made  it  possible 
to  can  prunes  and  some  types  of  cherries  which  could  not  be  canned  successfuily 
with  hot  rolled  tin  plate.  Cans  containing  other  types  of  acid  fruits  which  could 
not  be  kept  longer  than  eighteen  months  without  risk  of  becoming  unsalable,  can 
now  be  kept  as  long  as  seven  years.  Its  improved  workability  has  materially 
facilitated  fabrication. 

All  modem  tin  plate  has  a  much  more  uniform  coating  of  tin  due  in  part  to 
improved  smoothness  in  the  surface  of  the  black  plate  ob  which  the  tin  is  applied. 
This  improved  surface,  which  is  important  in  aU  uses  of  tin  plate,  is  illustrated 
by  the  following  photomicrographs  (p.  14113). 

The  purchaser  of  modern  tin  plate  has  less  waste  in  trimming  the  sheets  to  the 
size  and  shape  required  for  his  purposes  since  modern  tin  plate  is  much  more 
accurate  in  its  dimensions  than  was  the  tin  plate  of  fifteen  years  ago.  In^'eased 
uniformity  of  thickness  has  contributed  to  the  economical  use  of  high  speed 
machines  with  automatic  feeders  in  the  can-making  industry,  by  eliminating  the 
necessity  of  frequent  adjustments  in  the  machines  and  has  also  resulted  in  a  reduc- 
tion in  sheet  damage. 

It  is  estimated  that,  due  to  the  improved  quality  of  modem  tin  plate,  the  average 
weight  of  tin  plate  used  for  any  given  purpose  has  decreased  about  10%,  which, 
at  present  prices,  would  mean  a  reduction  of  about  20  cents  per  base  box. 

Formerly,  a  relatively  high  number  of  sheets  of  the  tin  plate  were  damaged  in 
transit  to  the  purchaser's  plant  due  to  twisted  and  bent  edges.  The  modern, 
much  more  compact  and  better  protected  packages,  made  possible  by  the  almost 
perfect  uniformity  of  the  sheets,  have  greatly  reduced  these  losses. 

In  1936  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  developed  and  introduced  a  new 
low«r^^riced  type  of  tin  plate,  electrolytically  plated,  called  "Ferrostan".  It  is 
being  used  to  replace  the  more  expensive  tin  plate  in  cans  for  baking  powder, 
coffee  and  similar  "dry  pacH"  and  has  made  possible  the  economical  packaging 
of  various  additional  commodities  for  convenient  distribution. 


CONCENTHATinN  OF   EOONOMIC  POWER 


14111 


14112 


CONCENTRATION  OF  EOONOMIC  POWKH 


KCTi 
ft.CC 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14113 


14114  CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

In  1933  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  developed  and  introduced  a  light 
coated  terne  plate  as  a  substitute  for  tin  plate  at  a  substantially  reduced  price. 
Although  never  used  where  the  surface  would  be  in  contact  with  food,  since  its 
coating  contains  a  substantial  amount  of  lead,  it  has  been  extensively  used  in 
cans  for  paint,  varnish  and  oil. 

Structural  Steel 

Tlie  use  of  an  improved  series  of  beams,  known  as  wide  flange  beams,  developed 
in  their  modem  efficient  form  during  the  last  twelve  to  thirteen  years,  has  per- 
mitted the  following  estimated  construction  savings: 

Higher  tier  buildings 20% 

Lower  tier  buildings  and  heaviest  mil]  buildings 15% 

Short  bridges  where  wide  flange  beams    are    substituted 

for  built  up  girders 15%  to  20% 

Large  bridges  and  light  mill  buildings 5%  to  10% 

Bulkheads,  seawalls  and  similar  retaining  walls  can  now  be  built  of  modern 
improved  steel  sheet  piling  more  than  twice  as  strong  as  was  possible  with  the 
steel  sheet  piling  of  five  or  six  years  ago.  Despite  its  doubled  strength,  this  im- 
proved piling,  known  as  Z  piling,  costs  only  7%  more  per  square  foot  than  the  best 
section  available  five  or  six  years  ago.  Before  the  introduction  of  Z  piling,  in 
order  to  obtain  equivalent  strength  it  was  necessary  to  reinforce  and  strengthen 
the  older  type  of  section,  involving  additional  steel  and  increased  fabrication  costs. 

A  new  type  of  steel  foundation  pile,  introduced  in  1935,  has  made  possible 
savings  ranging  from  10%  to  40%  over  competitive  forms  of  construction  for 
bridges,  buildings  and  other  structures,  and  has  made  possible  the  reclamation 
of  many  building  sites. 

In  1934  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  introduced  a  new  type  of  steel 
bridge  floor  for  use  with  concrete  or  asphalt  but  weighing  less  than  the  reinforced 
concrete  then  used.  This  has  been  a  great  step  toward  more  economical  bridge 
building,  since  the  weight  of  the  bridge  flooring,  and  not  that  of  the  traffic,  which 
is  always  light  by  comparison,  determines  the  size  of  the  foundations  and  super- 
structure. Its  lighter  weight  makes  possible  lighter  and  less  expensive  founda- 
tions and  superstructures  in  new  bridges,  and  has  often  extended  the  useful  life 
of  old  bridges.  It  has  also  been  used  to  increase  the  load  carrying  capacity  of  old 
bridges  with  only  minor,  inexpensive  changes  or  additions  to  the  existing  struc- 
ture.    Under  favorable  conditions,  it  costs  no  more  than  leinforced  concrete  slabs. 

Late  in  1937,  an  all  steel,  open  lattice-work  type  of  floor,  for  use  without 
concrete  or  asphalt,  was  introduced.  Its  exceedingly  light  weight  makes  it 
particularly  fitted  for  the  lifting  spans  of  draw  bridges  and  its  open  lattice-work 
character  makes  it  very  useful  in  states  where  snow  removal  is  a  problem.  Though 
it  costs  approximately  twice  as  much  as  reinforced  concrete  slabs,  it  permiis  more 
than  offsetting  economies,  in  machinery  and  power  required  for  the  lifting' of. 
draw  bridges,  and  in  reduced  maintenance  and  snow  removal  costs. 

One  or  the  other  of  these  types  of  floors  has  already  been  used  in  nearly  500 
old  or  new  bridges,  including  its  use  in  New  York  City  in  reflooring  three  main 
bridges  and  flooring  one  new  bridge. 

Stainless  Steel 

Stainless  stee  ,  although  only  introduced  on  a  large  scale  during  the  last  ten 
years,  has  already  replaced  other  types  of  steel  and  other  competitive  products 
in  many  uses  where  ability  to  withstand  high  temperatures  or  resistance  to 
corrosion  is  a  factor.  It  has  considerably  red^iced  upkeep  and  replacement  costs 
when  it  has  been  used,  because  of  its  long  life  due  to  its  high  strength  and  cor- 
rosion resistance,  and  because  its  hard,  permanently  bright  surface  does  not 
require  repeated  painting  and  is  not  worn  away  by  scouring. 

Stainless  steel  has  been  quite  generally  adopted  in  the  dairy  industry  for 
vessels,  pipes  and  other  pasteurizing  and  bottling  equipment.  It  has  been  found 
to  be  the  outstanding  commercial  metal  completely  insoluble  in  milk  cooling  from 
the  pasteurizing  temperature  and  its  surface  can  easily  be  kept  clean  and  sanitary. 
It  has  beei;  extensively  used  recently  in  the  construction  of  tank  trucks  for 
carrying  milk. 

It  has  also  been  extensively  used  in  the  food  processing  and  packing  industries, 
for  reasons  of  hygiene  and  economy.  It  has  been  installed  in  the  pineapple 
canning  plants  in  Hawaii,  as  it  has  proven  to  be  the  only  commercial  metal 
which  successfully  resists  the  action  of  pineapple  juice. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14115 

Enamel  and  glass  ware  equipment,  considered  a  great  step  forward  when 
introduced  in  the  dairy,  food  processing  and  packing  industries,  have  now  been 
largely  replaced  by  stainless  steel  because  their  great  weight  and  fragility  made 
transportation  costly  and  repairing  impracticable. 

Due  to  its  resistance  to  corrosion  and  its  high  strength  relative  to  its  weight, 
it  has  gained  a  constantly  wider  and  more  varied  use  in  the  building  industry 
generally,  for  such  parts  as  doors,  hinges,  window  moldings  and  restaurant  counters. 
It  is  particularly  adapted  for  the  making  of  pipes  and  tubes  for  use  in  the  chemical 
industry  and  in  other  industries  employing  equipment  subject  to  severe  cor- 
rosive influences. 

Modern  drums  of  stainless  steel  are  now  replacing  wooden  barrels  in  the  ship- 
ment of  beverages  and  syrups,  furnishing  extra  strength,  durability  and  perfect 
protection  of  the  contents.  The  ability  to  cleanse  completely  the  inside  of  such 
containers  is  making  it  possible  to  use  the  same  containers  almost  indefinitely. 

Current  developments  indicate  the  possibiUty  of  adopting  extremely  thin  and 
strong  stainless  steel  strip  for  use  in  airplane  wings  and  bodies,  permitting  welding 
instead  of  riveting,  therebyXreducing  wind  resistance  and  improving  operating 
efficiency. 

Although  its  initial  cost  per  unit  weight  is  somewhat  higher  than  that  of  the 
produces  which  it  has  replaced,  its  increasingly  wide  use  has  been  due  to  the 
fact  that  the  initial  cost  has  been  more  than  offset  by  the  subsequent  reduction 
in  expense  of  upkeep  and  replacement  and  by  the  hghter  weights  required  because 
of  its  higher  strength. 

Alloy  Steels 

The  science  of  predicting  and  controlling  the  properties  of  alloy  steels  which 
will  result  from  "heat  treating"  has  made  very  great  progress  in  the  last  fifteen 
and  even  in  the  last  five  years.  By  heat-treatment  is  meant  the  modification 
of  properties  through  the  agency  of  heating  the  steel  to  a  fairly  high  temperature 
and  applying  thereafter  a  controlled  cooling  rate  (as  in  quenching)  and  a  reheating 
if  desired.  The  steel  itself,  however,  must  fit  the  heat-treatment  and  vice-versa. 
It  is  now  possible  to  predict  and'control  such  properties  as  hardness,  toughness  or 
resiliency  with  a  remarkable  accuracy,  absolutely  unknown  fifteen  years  ago. 

This  is  very  important  in  all  mass  production  industries,  such  as  in  the  auto- 
mobile industry,  where  it  is  common  to  heat  treat  parts  made  of  alloy  steel. 
Modern  manufacturing  methods  in  these  industries  are  based  upon  the  fact 
that  alloy  steels  of  given  specifications,  though  made  at  different  mills,  at  different 
times  and  under  varying  conditions,  when  heat  treated  in  the  routine  of  production 
will  have  standard  properties. 

The  inability  to  predict  these  properties  accurately  made  it  necessary,  formerly, 
to  provide  for  a  comparatively  wide  margin  of  safety  through  the  use  of  excess 
weight  or  extra  alloy  content.  Equal  or  superior  efficiency  can  now  be  obtained 
by  the  use  of  lighter  weight  parts  made  of  less  expensive  steel  with  a  lower  aUoy 
content. 

A  reduction  of  15%  to  20%  in  the  average  weight  of  automobile  transmission 
gears,  for  example,  has  resulted  from  these  improvements  and  analogous  v/eight 
reductions  of  varying  degrees,  have  been  made  in  the  many  other  parts  made  of 
alloy  steel,  without  sacrifice  of  service  value. 

Alloy  steels  are  generally  sold  in  the  form  of  bai-s  to  manufacturers,  who  usually 
forge,  cut  and  machine  them  into  the  desired  part  and  then  heat  treat  them  to 
provide  varying  degrees  and  types  of  properties.  It  was,  until  recently,  con- 
sidered almost  impossible  to  control  the  depth  to  which  steel  would  harden  when 
heat  treated.  As  a  result  a  relatively  brittle  core  to  a  part  was  often  unavoidable 
in  obtaining  a  surface  of  the  required  hardness.  Steel  can  now  be  produced  which, 
when  heat-treated,  will  have  the  desired  hardness  on  the  wearing  surface  and  a 
far  lesser  degree  of  hardness  in  the  center,  thus  reducing  the  brittleness  and 
prolonging  the  life  of  the  part. 

The  ability  to  control  the  size  of  the  small  crystals  or  grains  of  which  steel  is 
composed  has  also  had  a  distinct  share  in  the  improvement  of  alloy  steels  as 
different  size  grains  produce  different  properties.  No  technology  of  grain  control 
existed  even  twelve  years  ago. 

The  greater  refinement  in  the  properties  of  allo^'  steels  has  increased  the  number 
of  standard  alloy  steels  listed  by  a  leading  producer  from  39  in  1924  to  168  in 
1938.  This  has  obviously  given  the  users  of  these  steels  far  greater  latitude  of 
choice  in  sheeting  the  steel  best  fitted  to  their  needs. 

Although  in  general  the  prices  of  alloy  steels  have  been  substantially  reduced 
since  1924,  the  large  number  of  standard  types  makes  it  impractical  to  indicate 


14116  CONi'F-NTRATTON  OF  ECONOMIC  POWFvR 

the  exact  measure  of  price  change  in  each.  However,  as  examples,  the  price  of 
two  common  types -has  been  reduced  approximately  15%  and  the  price  of  two 
other  common  types  has  been  reduced  approximately  11%. 

High  Tensile  Strength  Steels 

Great  savings  have  been  eflfected  by  the  railroads  through  the  use  of  a  new 
type  of  steel  developed  by  the  United  States  Steel  Corporation  and  commerci- 
ally introduced  in  1934  under  the  trade  name  of  COR-TEN. 

By  the  end  of  1938,  there  were  in  service  19,249  freight  cars  and  over  1,000 
passenger  cars  made  in  whole  or  in  part  of  COR-TEN.  COll-TEN  has  a  yield 
point  50%  to  100%  higher  than  plaia  carbon  structural  steel,  combined  with 
four  to  six  times  its  resistance  to  atmospheric  corrosion.  It  is  possible,  therefore, 
to  build  railroad  cars  of  this  material  at  a  substantial  weight  reduction  without 
decreased  strength  or  durability. 

It  is  possible  to  construct  freight  cars  made  of  COR-TEN  weighing  from  10% 
to  22%  less  than  cars  of  conventional  construction  made  of  plain  carbon  steel 
with  all  the  subsequent  operating  economies  which  this  reduction  in  weight 
entails.  Despite  its  improved  properties,  the  cost  of  a  COR-TEN  freight  car 
has  been  found  to  be  no  greater  than  that  of  the  conventional  carbon  steel  freight 
car  when  full  advantage  is  taken  of  the  superior  properties  of  COR-TEN  to 
effect  weight  reductions. 

Even  if  the  cost  of  a  freight  car  made  of  COR-TEN  were  greater  than  the  cost 
of  a  corresponding  car  made  of  plain  carbon  steel,  the  operating  economies 
resulting  from  its  use  are  so  important  that  its  widespread  use  would  be  economi- 
cally justified. 

It  is  estimated  that  it  costs  $18  a  year  to  haul  a  ton  of  weight  over  an  average 
annual  operating  mileage  of  11,000  miles  per  car.  The  average  reduction  of  2.4 
tons  in  dead  weight  in  each  of  these  19,249  freight  cars,  due  to  the  use  of  COR- 
TEN,  has  therefore  resulted  in  an  annual  average  saving  to  the  railroads  of 
approximately  $43.20  per  car,  a  total  saving  of  approximately  $830,000  per  year 
throughout  the  life  of  these  cars.  If  the  saving  is  considered  in  terms  of  addi- 
tional carrying  capacity,  each  of  these  freight  cars,  if  loaded  to  the  limit,  has  an 
added  annual  revenue-paying  capacity  of  2.4  tons.  Over  an  annual  operating 
mileage  of  11,000  miles  per  car,  this  represents  a  carrying  capacity  of  26,400 
ton-miles  more  than  that  of  a  conventional  car  built  of  plain  carbon  steel.  The 
19,249  COR-TEN  freight  cars  can,  therefore,  be  said  to  have  provided  a  total 
additional  annual  revenue-paying  capacity  of  508,173,600  ton-miles. 

The  experience  of  railroads  in  effecting  such  economies  through  the  use  of 
COR-TEN  has  led  to  its  increasingly  wide  use  in  many  other  industries  with 
attendant  large  savings  to  the  users. 

The  performance  of  this  material  has  resulted  in  the  development  of  other 
similar  and  competitive  steels. 

Steel  Pipe  and  Tubes 

The  service  qualities  of  all  steel  pipe  and  tube  have,  in  general,  greatly  increased 
since  1924.  A  few  typical  examples  of  the  type  of  improvement  are  sufficient  to 
indicate  this  progress. 

One  of  the  chief  beneficiaries  of  the  improvements  in  steel  pipe  and  tubes  has 
been  the  oil  industry.  By  the  use  of  new  seamless  oil  well  casing  pipe  and  oil 
well  drill  pipe  with  numerous  new  types  of  special  threaded  joints,  it  is  now 
possible  to  drill  wells  to  dfepths  of  approximately  three  miles  as  opposed  to  the 
maximum  depth  of  5,000  feet  in  1924. 

In  order  to  suspend  lengths  of  casing  pipe  as  long  as  13,000  feet  and  weighing 
up  to  300,000  pounds,  it  has  become  necessary  to  produce  steels  with  tensile 
strengths  up  to  125,000  pounds  and  with  resistance  to  external  pressure  up  to 
10,000  pounds. 

Drilling  such  deep  wells  makes  necessary  a  string  of  drill  pipe  weighing  up  to 
200,000  pounds  which  is  hung  in  tension  and  rotated  at  speeds  varying  from  100 
to  400  revolutions  per  minute.  This  pipe  is  therefore  subjected  to  tensile  stress 
from  hanging,  torsional  stress  from  the  rotary  movement,  and  alternate  bending 
stresses  at  the  tool  joints. 

The  deep  drilling  made  possible  by  these  improved  types  of  casing  and  drill 
pipe  has  permitted  successful  redrilling  at  deeper  levels  of  oil  fields,  notably  in 
California,  which  had  been  a«bandoned  for  failure  to  produce  at  the  former  maxi- 
mum drilling  depth,  and  has  also  opened  up  new  reservoirs  of  oil  in  Texas, 
L^-tisiana  and  Colorado. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14117 

In  modern  oil  refining  plants,  highly  alloyed  seamless  steel  tubes,  with  from 
10,000  to  60,000  hours  of  useful  life,  have  replaced  tubes  which  rarely  lasted  more 
than  2,000  to  6,000  hours.  Today,  it  is  possible  to  design  tubular  apparatus  for 
use  in  refining  to  carry  unit  stresses  between  10,000  and  25,000  pounds  at  1,000° 
F.,  greatly  increasing  the  safety  factor  in  operation  and  making  an  enormous 
saving  in  weight  of  equipment. 

Improvements  in  the  steam  boiler  industry  have  been  largely  associated  with 
improvements  in  boiler  tubes,  superheater  tubes  and  steam  pipe  through  which 
steam  is  conveyed.  In  1924,  due  to  the  fact  that  the  industry  was  limited  to 
the  use  of  low  carbon  steel  boiler  plate  and  tubes,  few  steam  plants  operated  at 
pressures  above  500  pounds  and  at  steam  temperatures  above  700°  F.  Through 
the  use  of  modern  seamless  boiler  tubes  of  alloy  steel,  boilers  are  now  constructed 
for  pressures  up  to  2,500  pounds  and  temperatures  of  1,000°  F.  These  tubes  will 
resist  the  most  severe  oxidation  and  corrosion  which  boiler  service  conditions 
impose. 

All  of  these  increases  in  quality  have  been  effected  with  a  lowering  of  price  to 
the  public,  except  that  boiler  tubes  have  increased  in  price  because  of  the  extra 
cost  necessary  to  produce  the  very  great  increase  in  quality  required  for  high 
temperatures  and  high  pressures  which  were  totally  unknown  fifteen  years  ago. 

Rails 

Railroad  engineers  fully  appreciate  that  the  railroads  are  now  receiving  rails 
substantially  improved  in  quality  and  dependability.  Although,  within  the  last 
15  years,  the  speeds  of  passenger  and  freight  trains  have  increased,-  on  the  aver- 
age, approximately  70%  and  55%,  respectively,  and  wheel  loads  have  increased 
between  40%  and  80%,  it  is  the  consensus  of  opinion,  among  producers  and 
buyers  of  rails,  that  the  modern  rail  will  last  longer,  wear  better  and  result  in 
fewer  failures  in  service  than  the  rails  produced  15  or  20  years  ago.  The  price 
is  approximately  the  same. 

In  considering  the  price  of  rails,  it  should  always  be  borne  in  mind  that  even 
so-called  worn  out  rails  are  sold  by  the  railroads  as  prime  scrap*.  The  average 
monthly  price  of  this  type  of  scrap  at  Pittsburgh  for  the  period  1924-1938  was 
$14.30  a  ton  or  34%  of  the  average  monthly  price  of  rails  during  that  period.  At 
present  the  price  of  old  rails  as  scrap  ranges  from  $22  to  $25  a  ton,  or  approxi- 
mately 60%  of  the  present  price  of  rails. 

Lower  material,  labor  and  upkeep  costs  have  resulted  from  increasing  the  stand- 
ard length  of  rails  from  33  feet  to  39  feet  at  no  increase  in  price  despite  the  fact 
that  changes  in  length  or  weight  entail  comprehensive  and  costly  changes  in  steel 
works  and  rolling  mill  equipment.  Some  railroads  order  45  foot  rails  and  serious 
consideration  is  being  given  to  the  advisability  of  using  rails  up  to  100  feet  or  more 
in  length. 

The  increased  dependability  of  modern  rails  is  due  to  the  improved  quality  of 
the  steel  as  verified  by  increasingly  severe  testing  and  inspection  standards. 

Formerly  one  specimen  of  rail  from  each  of  the  25  to  30  ingots  in  each  heat  were 
tested  by  dropping  a  2,000  pound  wedge  shaped  steel  weight  on  the  top  of  each 
specimen  from  heights  ranging  from  17  feet  for  the  lightest  rails  to  20  feet  for  the 
heaviest  rails.  Recently  the  maximum  height  of  drop  was  increased  to  22  feet. 
If  all  specimens  passed  this  test,  one  specimen  was  broken  and  its  interior  structure 
examined.  If  any  specimen  failed  to  pass  these  tests,  the  top  rail  in  each  ingot 
was  clafisified  for  less  severe  service  and  placed  in  a  lower  price  category. 

Some  railroads  now  require  that  a  specimen  from  each  ingot  be  subjected  to 
both  tests  (i.  e..  drop  test  and  fracture  inspection)  and  that,  if  on  examination  of 
the  test  fracture,  a  specimen  is  rejected,  other  tests  be  made  from  specimens  cut 
progressively  from  the  rails  of  that  ingot.  Under  the  requirements  of  this  pro- 
gressive test,  rails  failing  to  meet  the  test  are  not  accepted  even  as  lower  priced 
rails  but  are  rejected  and  scrapped. 

Each  of  these  tests  is  supervised  by  separate  inspectors  representing  the  rail 
producer  and  the  railroad.  The  examination  of  the  cross  section  of  the  rail  and 
its  approval  or  rejection  is,  in  many  cases,  a  matter  of  judgment  with  respect  to 
which  the  railroad  inspectors  have,  as  a  practical  matter,  fairly  arbitrary  powers. 
The  requirements  of  this  test  and  the  standards  of  straightness  and  smoothness 
have  become  so  exacting,  that  rails,  which  would  have  been  considered  good  aver- 
age rails  fifteen  or  twenty  years  ago  and  completely  acceptable,  are  rejected  today 
by  both  the  mill  engineers  and  the  railroad  inspectors. 

Special  treatments  have  recently  been  devised  and  introduced  which  appear  to 
remove  one  cause  for  one  of  the  most  troublesome  types  of  rail  failures,  known  as 
the  '-'transverse  fissure".     This  is  a  eeparajion  of  the  metal  inside  the  head  of  the 


14118       CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 

rail  developed  by  flexure  in  service  and  is  not  apparent  until  failure  of  the  rail. 
The  gradual  introduction  since  1932  of  rails  subjected  to  one  or  the  other  of  these 
special  thermal  treatments  has  remarkably  reduced  failures  due  to  transverse 
fissures.  The  figures  of  the  American  Railway  Engineering  Association  indicate 
that  in  rails  rolled  during  the  five  years  1932-1936  there  were  only  9  such  failures 
in  the  fi  rst  year  of  service  as  compared  with  343  such  failures  in  the  first  year  of 
service  in  rails  rolled  during  1927-1931. 

One  of  the  treatments  against  transverse  fissures,  the  Brunorizing  process, 
developed  and  introduced  by  United  States  Steel  Corporation,  produces  rails 
which  are  also  much  more  resistant  to  shock  at  low  temperatures,  an  imjjortant 
safety  factor  in  parts  of  the  country  where  the  rails  must  stand  much  zero  or 
sub-zero  weather. 

The  increased  inspection  and  control  in  the  rail  mills  in  the  making  of  the  steel 
in  the  open  hearth  furnace,  in  the  rolling  and  in  the  cooling  and  other  special  re- 
quirements in  connection  with  rail  making  have  all  increased  the  manufacturing 
costs  of  rails  and,  contrary  to  the  general  trend,  more  men  are  required  to  operate 
a  rail  mill  today,  than  fifteen  or  twenty  years  ago 

Wire  Products 

Improvements  in  wire  products  have  been  due  in  part  to  the  increased  perfection 
of  rods  from  which  wire  is  made,  resulting  from  scientific  selection  of  ores,  classifi- 
cation of  raw  materials  and  other  improvements  in  steel  making.  Improved 
modern  wire  making  machinery  and  practices  have  also  contributed  to  this  im- 
provement. Typical  illustrations  from  a  few  of  the  numerous  wire  products  are 
sufl^cient  to  indicate  the  general  improvement  in  quality. 

The  resiliency  of  spring  wire,  for  example,  has  generally  increased  in  the  order 
of  magnitude  of  50%.  Resistance  to  fatigue,  due  to  repeated  flexing,  as  in  the 
case  of  springs  usea  in  automobile  engines,  has  been  greatly  increased,  thereby 
prolonging  the  life  of  the  spring.  Although  the  price  of  spring  wire  has  been  re- 
duced since  1924,  it  is  estimated  that  its  reliability  and  service  has  increased  from 
100%  to  500%,  depending  updn  the  type  of  wire. 

The  uniformity  in  size,  form  and  physical  properties  of  nails,  rivets,  bolts  and 
other  similar  products,  requiring  the  forming  c.i  a  head  by  pressure  exerted  on  the 
end  of  the  wire  at  high  speed  has  greatly  improved  due  to  the  improved  quality 
of  the  wire  and  wire  bars  from  which  they  are  made.  Today  practically  perfect 
Leads  are  produced,  while  formerly  irregularities  in  the  wire  resulted  in  considers 
ble  irregularity  in  the  shapes  of  heads  which  caused  failures  in  service. 

The  uniformity  of  nail  wire  is  such  that  since  1928  it  has  been  a  standard  require- 
ment that  the  number  of  nails  per  pound  must  not  vary  beyond  5%  of  the  stand- 
ard number.  As  any  slight  variation  in  the  thickness  of  the  wire  would  cause 
considerable  variation  in  the  number  of  nails,  such  a  narrow  limit  of  variation  was 
formerly  impossible.  The'  importance  of  this  is  obvious  to  a  buyer  of  nails  who 
buys  nails  by  weight.  Likewise,  the  increased  accuracy  in  the  gauge  of  wire  is 
extremely  important  to  the  purchaser  of  wire  by  weight. 

The  life  of  galvanized  wire  has  been  greatly  increased  through  the  improved 
quahty  of  the  galvanizing.  It  is  now  a  standard  requirement  that  such  wire 
must  bend  ai  )und  its  own  diameter  without  roughening  the  galvanized  coating,  a 
requirement  which  could  not  have  been  met  commercially  a  few  years  ago. 

It  is  probahle  that  few  people  realize  the  important  part  wire  has  played  in  the 
development  of  the  modern  automobile  tire.  Nevertheless,  the  bead  of  automobile 
tires  has  for  many  years  been  strengthened  by  the  use  of  wire.  Improved  methods 
in  the  manufacture  of  wire  have  resulted  in  the  production  of  wire  for  this  purpose 
having  a  tensile  strength  of  approximately  300,000  pounds  per  square  inch,  which 
is  from  25%  to  50%  higher  than  the  tensile  strength  of  wire  used  10  to  20  years  ago. 
In  addition,  this  wire  is  now  required  to  meet  physical  tests  for  toughness,  such  as 
torsion  and  elongation,  both  before  and  after,  it  is  subjected  to  the  vulcanizing 
process.  These  improved  physical  properties  have  permitted  a  reduction  in  the 
size  and  number  of  wires  necessary  for  strengthening  the  tires  and  have  also 
materially  contributed  to  the  increased  life  and  dependability  of  modern  tires. 

General  Improvement  in  Quality 

In  general,  the  quality  of  the  steel  used  in  all  steel  products  today  is  far  more 
uniform  and  dependable  and  better  suited  to  the  needs  of  the  users  than  fifteen 
years  ago  due  to  genera]  improvements  in  steelmaking. 

The  basic  mateiials  from  which  pig  iron  is  made  are  now  selected  and  graded  for 
uniformity  which  makes  a  much  superior  and  more  uniform  iron. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14119 

Chemical  control  of  practically  all  processes,  other  than  the  strictly  mechanical, 
has  become  universal.  Pyrometry  for  the  measurement  and  control  of  tempera- 
tures has  been  developed  and  applied  in  all  important  processes. 

Slag  control  in  the  open  hearth  furnaces  has  permitted  the  production  of  the 
several  kinds  of  steels  for  various  uses  with  a  dependability  and  an  accuracy  that 
was  not  even  approximated  several  years  ago. 

The  increasingly  greater  approach  to  laboratory  standards  of  precision  and  qual- 
ity in  the  commercial  production  of  millions  of  tons  of  steel  every  year,  has  required 
the  training  and  maintenance  of  a  large  staflF  of  metallurgical  engineers,  upon  whom 
practical  operating  men  have  necessarily  come  to  rely  more  and  more  in  the  turn- 
ing out  of  a  modern  marketable  product. 

In  short,  during  the  last  fifteen  years,  steel  making  has  been  changed  from  an 
art  to  a  science  with  the  resulting  general  improvement  in  all  steels  and  with  ac- 
companying benefits  to  the  users  of  steel. 


Exhibit  No.  2183 


Fig. 

RELATION  OF  INDUSTRIAL  PRODUCTION.  EXCLUDING 
IRON   AND  STEEL,  TO  STEEL  SALES 


28/ 

X 

. 

Average 
relation 

27 

lb/ 

35^   y^'^^ 

/                  23 

•  ■30 

i 

■38.         y 
^•■33 

•22 

*iai9 

•  ■20 

\z      --" 

15  20  25 

ESTIMATED   DOMESTIC   STEEL   SHIPMENTS 


30  35 

[MILLION  TONS) 


NEC   35966   SUB 


14120  CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWER 

Exhibit  No.  2184 

CONTRAST  IN  PRODUCTION-PROFIT  COMPUTATIONS 


MR   T  W   LIPPERT,  METALLURGICAL  EDITOR,   IRQN  AGE 
(Based  on  data  for  two  large  componies) 


U.  S.  STEEL   CORPORATION 


CONCENTRATION  OF  iDCONOMIC  POWER 
Exhibit  No.  2185 


14121 


Table  I. — Reconciliation  of  Total  Costs  Before  Bond  Interest  and  Inter- Company 
Items  in  "Analysis''  and  Registration  Statement,  19S6-S7 — U.  S.  Steel  Cor- 
poration 


1936 


Cost  before  Bond  Interest  and  Inter-Company  Items  as  pjr 
"Analysis  (Table  5,  columns  (2)  (3)  &>Xi)": 

Total -v- 


$770,713,718 


Operating  Costs 

Idle  Plant  Expense. 
Purchase  Discount. 


1,269,970,378 

1, 136, 149 

-1,815.869 


1, 035, 128, 

1, 396, 

-1,455, 


769, 564, 100 
2, 089, 259 
-939, 641 


Break-down  of  Total  Costs  as  per  Registration  Statement: 
Total - - 


770,713,718 


General  administrative  and  selling  expenses 

Payments  under  pension  plan  to  U.  S.  Steel  and  Carnegie 
Pension  Fund 

Taxes  (other  than  Federal  income  and  surtax).. 

Taxes  (state  and  Federal  social  security  and  railroad  re- 
tirement)  

Idle  plant  expenses 

Depreciation  and  depletion...' 

Plant  and  Organization  siyvey  expenses 

Discount  on  Purchases 

Reversal  of  provisions  under  Railroad  Retirement  Act 
of  1935 - 

Cost  of  goods  sold,  operating  expenses  of  trafasportation 
common  carriers  and  miscellaneous  operations 


,415,904 
,  136, 149 
,  589, 159 
,  756, 776 
,815,869 

.744,729 

,772,329 


7, 642, 026 
37, 220, 467 

4,081,587 
1, 396, 989 
55,466,762 
1,379,829 
-1,455,169 


7, 362, 723 
34, 541, 519 


2, 089, 259 

47, 801, 390 

285,003 

-939,641 


Sources:  "Exhibit  No.  1416"  and  Registration  Statement  (Form  At2)  submitted  to  the  Securities  and 
Exchange  Commission. 

Table  II. — Comparison  of  Break-Down  of  Lumped  Costs  in  the  "Arfalysis"  and  in 
Registration  Statement,  19S5-S7  ' — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 


1937 

1936 

1935 

Breakdown  of  Lumped  Costs  as  per  "Analysis": 
Total.. 

$1, 143, 773, 008 

$929,880,828 

$680,858,276 

Payroll ^... 

Other  Expenses 

426,330,944 
343,494,434 
373,947,630 

328,070,724 
293, 599, 768 
308,210,336 

246,  508, 043 
197,911,220 
236, 439, 013 

Inter-Company  Items 

Breakdown  of  Lumped  Costs  as  per  Registration  Statement: 
Total 

1,143,773,008 

929,880,828 

680,858,276 

General  administrative  and  selling  expenses..., 

Plant  and  Organization  survey  expenses 

44,668,352 
1, 756, 776 

.-744,729 

110, 294, 824 

'7,650,787 
10,213,951 

16,892,758 
.953,  720, 009 

39,447,790 

1,379,829 

1,396,989 

-1,455,169 

34, 613, 494 

285,003 

2, 089, 259 

939  641 

Idle  Plant  Expenses 

Discount  oii  Purchases 

Reversal  of  provisions  under  Railroad  Retirement  Act  of 
1935. 

Maintenance  and  repairs  (including  provisions  for  blast 
furnace  reUning,  oven  wall  relining  and  rebuilding  and 

-     85,589,705 

5, 492, 640 
7,860,403 

17, 461, 037 
772, 707, 604 

59,097,850 

2, 809, 295 
5, 249, 623 

14, 010, 938 
563, 642, 455 

Depreciation-,  depletion  and  amortizing  of  fixed  assets 
(credited  directly  to  property  plant  and  equipfnent).... 
Rents  and  Royalties 

Additions  to  Reserves  Charged  to  Cost  of  Goods  Sold, 
Etc.-TotalJ :...... 

Residual' 

'  "Lump  costs"  is  used  to  designate  the  total  "other  Expenses,"  "Payroll,"  and  "Inter-Company  Items" 
in  the  "Analysis."  It  is  the  same  as  total  costs  less  taxes,  depreciation,  pensions  and  bond  interest  (spe- 
cifically segregated  items  in  the  "Analysis,"  Table  8),  all  before  deducting  inter-company  items. 

'  There  may  be  some  duplication  between  reserve  additions  and  maintenance  and  repair  items.  The 
effect  of  such  duplication  would  be  to  lower  the  residual. 


14122 


CONCENTRATION  OP  ECONOMIC  POWE(R 


Table  II-A. — Additions  to  Reserves  Charged  to  Cost  of  Goods  Sold,  Etc.,  1935-37^- 
U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 


1937 

1936 

1935 

Total                         

$16,892,758 

$17,461,037 

$14,010,938 

General  contingent  reserves  currently  provided  by  charges  to  opera- 
tions and  held  for  purposes  arising  from  operating  activities 

Accident  and  hospital  reserves  currently  provided  through  charges 
to  operations  and  held  to  cover  expenditures  resulting  from  operat- 

9, 036, 960 

4.463,981 

273, 525 

930,016 

1,048,068 

527 

396,168 

730,814 

9,658,240 

3,879,490 

1,247,012 

791, 799 

1,361,740 

-184 

489, 773 

219,256 

7,228,531 

3,780,359 

1, 071, 976 

503  125 

Reserve.s  raised  by  current  accruals  for  purposes  of  absorbing  ex- 
traordinary expenses  in  specified  operations    ..              

Other  reserves  provided  and  held  for  specific  purposes  or  for  other 
genera!  contingencies  for  which  they  may  be  available 

Insurance  reserves  '         -  - 

826,642 
23,840 
309,663 
-89 
—9  970 

Reserves  for  sundry  marketable  securities  . 

Inventory  valuation  reserves 

Reserve  for  U.  S.  Steel  Corp.  stock  for  employes'  subscription.  . 

Reserves  account  outside  real  estate,  real  estate  mortgages  and 

43,244 

-645 

.-29,900 

-46, 170 
-55, 734 
-84, 185 

149, 764 
55  666 

Reserves  account  house  and  land  sales  installment  contracts  and 
mortgages  under  employes'  home  owning  plans 

Reserves  for  accounts  and  notes  receivable  not  colIectYble  within 

71,631 

'  Detail  for  "Additions  to  Reserves"  item  of  Table  II. 

>  Provided  by  charges  to  operation,  together  with  accretions  thereon,  are  available  for  absorbing  fire, 
windstorm  and  paM  of  the  marine  losses  of  subsidiaries.  The  subsidiaries  are  self-insurers  against  such 
losses  and  generally  do  not  insure  with  outside  insurance  companies.  Specific  funds  have  not  been  segre- 
gated for  these  reserves. 

Table  III. — Taxes  Other  Than  Federal  Income  and  Social  Security  Taxes, 
1927-38— U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 


Year 

Total 
Charged  to 
Costs  as  per 
"Analysis" 

Capital 
Stock 
Tax 

Total  Ex- 
cluding 
Capital 
Stock 

Lake 
Superior 
Iron  Ore 
Properties 

All  Other 
Properties 

Excise  and 
Miscella- 
neous 

Differ- 
ence" 

1927 

$34,817,116 
36,015,942 
37, 739, 322 
36,047,026 
33, 162,  707 
31, 943, 315 
33, 288, 485 
32,615,831 
34, 691, 330 
37,999,606 
45, 132, 333 
34,602,915 

$34, 817, 116 
36,015,942 
37,  739, 322 
36,047,026 
33, 162,  707 
31,444,131 
32, 289, 301 
30, 983, 323 
32, 954, 959 
36,a90,842 
43,203,328 
32, 602, 890 

1 

1928 

1929 

1930 

1931 

» $14, 215, 651 
12,681,884 
«  12, 735, 967 
13,859,408 
13,828,911 
15, 187, 324 
18, 197, 478 
12, 837, 735 

» $19, 858, 097 
U8, 950, 835 
•17,599,925 
17, 399, 374 
18,604,455 
20,209,831 
24, 685, 087 
19,207,090 

<  $93, 984 

1 105, 617 

«  288,  591 

•289,094 

480, 272 

407,906 

320,763 

558, 066 

-$1,004,925 

1932 

1933 

1934 

1935 

1936...... 

<  $499, 184 
999, 184 
1, 632,  508 
'  1,  736, 371 
1, 808,  764 
1,929,005 
2,000,025 

-294,205 
+1,664,818 
-564,653 
+41,321 
+385, 781 

'  Difference  between  accrued  tax  liabilities  and  amounts  charged  to  costs.    Breakdowns  in  1932-36 
Annual  Reports  show  accrued  liabilities  for  taxes;  Reports  for  other  years  show  actual  charges  to  costs. 
>  As  shown  in  1932  Annual  Report;  no  breakdown  given  in  1931  Report. 


'  Approximate  amount. 

*  Allocated  to  1932  although  paid  under  the  National  Industrial  Recovery  Ac 


_L-t  which  riecame  effective  in 

June  1933.   ~  ■       -       '       °    '■  ..-  .  ,     ^        ^ 

•  As  shown  in  1933  Annual  Report.  1932  Report  shows  $19,087,813  for  other  than  Lake  Snperi  ir  Iron  Ore 
Properties. 

»  As  shown  In  1934  Annual  Report;  1933  Report  shows  $13,314,519  for  Iron  Ore  properties  an  J  $17,869,925 
for  other  properties. 

'  As  shown  in  1936  report;  1935  report  shows  $1,759,922. 

Source:  Break-down  from  Annual  Reports. 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


14123 


Table  IV. —  Taxes  Other  Than  Federal  Inconie  and  Social  Security  Taxes,  1927- 
1938 — Recompvied  "Fixed"  and  "Variable"   Costs — U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 


Estimate  of 

"Fixed" 
Cost  per  year 

Estimate  of 
"Variable" 
C...  per  Ton 

r= 

$24,217,000 

$1,433 

.96 

iDCluding  1937: 

Totcl                                                     

29,950,000 

0. 691 

2,000,000 
27,950,000 

Other                            -t - - 

6.69i 

.714 

Excluding  1937: 

Total        

31,090,000 

0.514 

Capital  Stock  Taxes  (1938) 

2,000,000 
29, 090, 000 

Other'        - 

0. 514 

.788 

'  This  relation  approximates  the  one  for  1927-31  shown  in  Chart  2,  p.  13  of  the  "Analysis  " 
Source:  Based  upon'Annual  Reports  and  "Analysis." 

"  Table  V. — Maintenance  and  Repairs,  1927-38  ' —  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation 


Charge?  to  Costs 


From  Current  Expen. 


-  Charges  to 
1    Costs  in 


Other 


I  ExcesE  of 
Credits  to  I  Expendi- 
Reservc  tiires  * 


Weighted 
Tons  of 

Produi  ts 
Shipped 

(Millions) 


1927. 
1928 
1929 
1930. 
1931. 
1932 
1933 
1934. 
1935 


$113. 
106, 
107, 


875, 264 
684,913 
235, 214 
.';i2, 158 
419,  408 
112,622 
169, 688 
894,512 
978,  426 
126,  667 
304,054 
448, 926 


$91,035, 
85,  707, 
85, 900, 
7.1,411, 

21  [924! 

40,"'974,' 
47,  567, 
70,378, 


161  $22, 840, 103  $85,  626, 
302  20,977,611  79J'86, 
446  21,334,768  I  79,411, 
765      21,100.393  i  70.192, 

14,080,750  I  43,300. 
7, 187, 828  1  20,  628: 
8,279,732      '       "" 

11,919,714 

12, 410, 8-32 

15,  747, 807 


860 


30, 135, 
39, 183, 
45, 447, 
67, 262, 


,267  1 
,199  ; 


5,219, 
3, 038. 
1,296, 
1,754, 
1,  791, 
2, 119, 
3, 116, 
3,621, 
2, 100, 


$138, 
3, 537, 
1,799, 
1, 139, 


962. 

974, 
1, 567, 

720, 
-122, 
1.  342, 


13.0 
14.0 
15.1 
11.9 


6.2 
6.1 
7.6 
11.0 
13.2 
7.8 


■  Includes  a  portion  of  idle  plant  expenses. 

'  Expenditures  excluding  extraordinary  replacements  charged  to  depreciation  and  replacement  reserves. 

Source:  Annual  Reports,  except  weighted  tons  which  are  from  "Analysis." 
Table  VI. — Stripping  and  Development  Expenses,  1927-88 — L'.  S.  Steel  Corporation 


■  Year 

Charged 
to  Costs 

Charged  to 
Costs  in  Ex- 
cess of  E,x- 
penditures 

Weighted 
Tons  of 

Products 
Shipped 

(Millions) 

1                        Charged  to 

,,„           1    Charged      Costs  in  Ex- 

,       ^  ^-"^       ;    to  Costs       cess  of  Ex- 

i                       penditures 

Weighted 
Tons  of 
Products 

(MiUwns) 

1927 

1928 

1929— 

1930 

1931 

1932 

$4,431,341 
5, 073, 611 
6,218,468 
5,  224,  575 
2,963.640 
482, 575 

-$1,085,560 
.599.479 
1. 713,  361 
-949,  275 
-1.52,656 
-797,763 

13.-0 
14.0 
15.1 
11.9 

1933  -. :  $2,103,857  1      $1,006,073 

1934.. 1    2,  382,  .389  '           953,003 

1935 '    2,698,050  '        1,421,606 

1936. 5,431,607           3,291,631 

1937. :     7.557,125           .^  290,  267 

1938 !     2.622,625              477.360 

1                        1 

6.2 
6.1 
7.0 
11.0 
13.2 
7  8 

Source:  Annual  Reports,  except  for  weighted  tons  which  is  from  the  "Analysis.' 


124491— 41^pt.  26- 


14124 


CONOENTRATION  OF  p]<'ONOMIC  POWER 


Si  I 


s 

1 

El 

83 


\ 


/      \ 

/ 
\ 


"\ 


.<^ 


I 


—  g 


—  g 


,3     S5 


CONCENTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER  14125 


Exhibit  No.  2187 

THE   NET  REGRESSION  OF  VOLUME  ON   PRICE 


RELATIONSHIP  I 


'        1 
1          1 

i        i        1 

1                i                1 

1            ■ 

1 — [~l- 

i 

1        " 

1  i  ?*' 

.26    I 

: 

!             '            1 

RELATIONSHIP  E 


- 

..      ... 

20. 

/^ 

y 

..^ 

"         i 

c»  t.O  tj  8.4  te 


RELATIONSHIP! 


RELATIONSHIP  m 


\ 

—^ 

^3 

*" 

.„ 

i* 

♦s 

•?^ 

'^ 

"          1             i 

v 

\ 

.«* 

p 

.sr 

„  f« 

S8 

*^, 

7?^ 

C£HT$    PES  L». 

emmsire  poiec  of  Finisnee  tnct. 


It  t.o  u  t.4  t.e  t3 

CENTS    PCT  t». 

■  M/ar  o'  FmtDKO  srm  , 


14126 


CONCBNTRAaiON  OF  ECONOMIC  POWER 


i    1 


1 1  - 1 

fc  fe  •  ^ 

g  °  g  " 

g  8  ^! 


if 


SUPPLEMENTAL  DATA 


The  following  telegrams  have  no  connection  with  subjects  dealt 
with  in  this  volume;  they  are  included  in  the  record  to  authenticate 
certain  statements  made  by  Mr.  Eugene  Orvis  in  his  prepared  state- 
ment, admitted  to  the  record  as  "Exhibit  No.  1293"  and  included 
in  Hearings,  Part  16,  appendix,  p.  9330. 

[Telegram] 

Kansas  City,  Mo.,  October  10,  1939. 
James  Brackett, 

Secretary,  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee, 

Federal  Trade  Commissio-i.  Building,  Washington,  D.  C: 

We  have  been  advised  that  the  committee  desires  certain  information  from 
Great  Lakes  Pip-^  Line  Co.  relative  to  the  prepared  statement  presented  at  the 
oil-industry  hearing  by  Eugene  L.  Orvis.  The  owners  of  Great  Lakes  Pipe  Line 
Co.  are  Continental  Oil  Co.,  Midcontinent  Petroleum  Corporation,  Skelly  Oil  Co., 
The  Texas  Corporation,  The  Pure  Oil  Co.,  Sinclair  Refining  Co.,  Cities  Service 
Oil  Co.,  and  Phillips  Petroleum  Co.  The  members  of  the  traffic  committee  of 
Great  Lakes  Pipe  Line  Co.  and  the  company  bv  which  each  is  employed  are 
C.  A.  L.  Walker,  with  Great  Lakes  Pipe  Line  Co.;  Charles  Ervin,  with  the  Texas 
Corporation:  Henry  Hauseman,  with  the  Pure  Oil  Co.;  C.  A.  Hoimos,  with  Cities 
Service  Oil  Co.;  P.  H.  Kii.ns,  with  Continental  Oil  Co.;  C.  R.  Musgrave,  with 
Phillips  Petroleum  Co.;  J.  M.  ODay,  with  Sinclair  Refining  Co.;  H.  W.  Roe, 
with  Midcontinent  Petroleum  Corporation:  and  A.  F.  Winn,  with  the  Skelly 
Oil  Co. 

This  traffic  committee  is  an  advisory  group  whose  purpose  is  to  a.ssist  the  pipe- 
line management  to  correlate  the  cumbersome  pipe-line  operation  with  the 
requirements  of  all  shippers  and  the  regulations  of  the  Interstate  Commerce 
Commission,  '^he  recommendations  of  the  committee  are  in  no  wise  binding 
upon  the  pipe-line  management  or  upon  any  member  of  the  committee  nor  may 
any  shipping  representative  speak  for  the  pipe-line  company.  We  ha\e  examined 
the  minutes  of  the  traffic  committee  of  Great  Lakes  Pipe  Line  Co.  and  they  do 
not  contaiti  the  paragraphs  quoted  by  Mr.  Orvis  on  page  10  and  continuing  to  the 
top  of  page  11  of  his  prepared  statement;  however,  the  matters  appearing  in  the 
purported  minutes  were  discussed  on  several  occasions  with  the  traffic  managers 
of  the  shipping  companies  prior  to  item  60  on  page  13  of  Mr.  Orvis'  prepared 
statement  being  incorporated  in  the  tariffs  of  the  pipe-line  company. 

The  quotation  at  the  bottom  of  page  21  and  extending  over  to  the  top  of  page 
22  of  Mr.  Orvis'  prepared  statement  purports  to  be  an  excerpt  from  the  minutes 
of  a  meeting  held  June  23,  1938,  of  officials  of  tiie  companies  owning  Great  Lakes 
Pipe  Line  Co.  No  such  meeting  v.as  held.  The  quotation  is  an  excerpt  from  a 
letter  written  by  the  traffic  manager  of  the  pipe-line  company  to  the  traffic 
managers  of  the  various  shipping  companies. 

Haery  Moreland, 
Vice  President,  Great  Lakes  Pipe  Line  Co. 


[Telegram] 

Kansas  City,  Mo.,  October  10,  1939. 
James  Brackett, 

Secretary,  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee, 

Federal  Trade  Commission  Building,  Washington,  D.  C. 

Further  referring  to  my  telegram  to  you  dated  October  9,  the  paragraphs  quoted 

by  Mr.  Orvis  on  page  10  and  continuing  to  the  top  of  page  11  of  his  prepared 

statement  are  not  a  part  of  the  minutes  of  the  traffic  committee  of  Groat  Lakes 

Pipe  Line  Co.  but  are  undoubtedly  a  memorandum  expressing  the  views  of  the 

14127 


14128  COxNCBNTRATION  OF  ECONOMIC  POWDR 

traffic  committee  on  the  subjects  therein  referred  to  and  as  stated  in  my  earUer 
telegram  were  taken  Into  consideration  in  drafting  itepti,  60  of  Great  Lakes  Pipe 
Line  Co.  tariffs  which  is  correctly  quoted  on  page  I'S  of  Mr.  Orvis'  prepared 
statement.  The  copy  of  a  letter  which  you  have  dated  January  22,  1937,  trans- 
mitting the  minutes  of  the  meeting  of  the  traffic  committee  of  Great  Lakes 
Pipe  Line  Co.  held  at  Kansas  City,  Mo.,  January  19,  1937,  is  correct.  The  minutes 
as  attached  thereto  are  also  correct  except  that  the  heading  of  the  third  para- 
graph on  the  first  page  of  said  minutes  referring  to  Messrs.  Kuhns,  Okay  Winn, 
and  Stewart  should  read  "Members  absent"  instead  of  "Members  present." 
The  excerpt  which  you  have  of  the  minutes  of  the  meeting  of  the  traffic  committee 
held  at  Kansas  City,  October  9,  1936,  is  correct;  however,  the  reference  to  case 
2610  attached  to  this  excerpt  is  not  attached  to  the  recorded  minutes  of  the 
committee. 

The  reference  to  case  2610,  however,  is  undoubtedly  to  the  proposed  rate  of  6.9 
referred  to  in  the  excerpt.  The  copv  of  letter  which  you  have  dated  Januarv  22, 
1937,  signed  by  C.  A.  L.  Walker,  referring  to  W.  T.  L.  application  D-37-175  to 
Messrs.  Kuhns  and  others  is  correct.  We  have  been  unable  to  find  in  the  files  of 
Great  Lake^  Pipe  Line  Co.  copy  of  the  letter  purported  to  have  been  written  bv 
C.  A.  L.  Walker  to  R.  E.Stewart,  dated  May  11,  1937;  or  by  Mr.  Walker  to 
Continental  Oil  Co.  and  other  oil  companies,  dated  May  22,  1937;  or  by  R.  E. 
Stewart  to  Mr.  Walker  and  others,  dated  May  7, 1937;  however,  we  have  no  reason 
to  doubt  the  correctness  of  the  copies  of  these  three  letters  which  you  have,  and 
are  not  questioning  their  authenticity.  We  desire  to  add  that  the  question  of 
whether  the  intrastate  railroad  or  interstate  railroad  rate  is  applicable  from  the 
terminals  of  the  pipe-line  company  is  a  legal  t}uestion  and  the  determination  of 
that  question  has  no  connection  with  the  published  rates  of  the  pipe-line  company 
which  appear  in  its  tariffs. 

Harry  Moreland, 
Vice  President,  Great  Lakes  Pipe  Line  Co. 


INDEX 

Page 

A.  A.  A J3647,  13689,  13948 

Adams,  Henry  Carter 13716 

Agricultural  Adjustment  Act 13947 

Agriculture,  United  States  Department  of 13676,  13719-13720,  13975,  14119 

Agricultural  Economics,  Bureau  of 13676,13720,14119 

Bureau  of  Public  Roads 13975 

Secretary  of 1 3676 

Almanac  of  Canning  Industry  and  Iron  Age 14023 

American  Can  Co 14018-14019 

American  Car  &  Foundry  Co 13S9S 

American  PJconomic  Association 13983 

American  Iron  and  Steel  Institute 13848,  13850,  13852,  13854, 

13863,  13872,  13903,  13929,  13937,  13986,  14008,  14011,  14020 

American  Locomotive  Co 13898 

American  Metal  Market  Co 13940 

American  Railway  Car  Institute : 14016 

American  Railway  Engineering  Association 14118 

American  Rolling  Mill  Co 13903 

American  Sheet  &  Tin  Plate  Co 13808,  14106 

American  Statistical  Association 13898 

American  Steel  &  Wire  Co 13910,  14106 

"Annalist,  The" 13770-13771 

Appert,  Richard  H 1 13649-13650,  13671 

Asia  13722 

Association  of  American  Railroads 13969,  14003-14005-14009,  14015 

Association  of  National  Advertisers 13910-1391 1 

Atlas  Portland  Cement  Co 13749 

Automobile  Manufacturing  Association 13819, 

13983-13985.  13987,  13994-13996 

Austria 13863 

Ballinger,  J.  W 14004 

Banking  Act 13948 

Bean,  Dr.  Louis : 13597,13617,13632, 

13710,  13719-13720,  13723,  13729,  13732-13733,  13735-13741 
Examination  by,  of  U.  S.  Steel  Corporation  demand  analyses.    13720-13732 

Bensheimer,  J 13616 

Bethlehem  Steel  Corporation 13903 

Birmingham,  Ala 13900,  13958 

Bituminous  Coal  Act ' 13712 

F31ack,  J.  D_ 13937,13940 

Boeckh,  E.  H - 13964 

Borah,  Senator  William  E.,  in  memoriam 13648 

Buffalo . 13896,  13899 

Bureau  of  Business  Research 13617 

Bureau  of  Corporations,  United  States 13746 

Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue,  Alcohol  Tax  Unit 14025 

Bureau  of  Railwav  Economics 14003-14004.  14007-14008,  14015 

California _" 14116 

Cailiuann,  Dr.  Riidolf._,    . 13616 

Canada . 13903 

Carnegie-Illinois  Steel  Corporation -    -  13910, 

13953-139.54,  13958.  1397S,  13-.'-^0,  14106 

"Cartels" 1 13616 

Cash  costs 13600-13602 


II  INDEX 

Page 

Census  of  Manufacturea 13872,  13890, 

13895,  13914,  13979,  13983,  14018.  14024-14025,  14028,  14030 
Census,  United  States  Bureau  of.   13850,  13854,  13914,  13960,  13973,  13979,  14016 

Chamberlin,  Edwin... 13651,  13908 

Chevrolet 13990,  1 3993 

Chicago 13805,  13837,  13899,  13958,  13976 

Cincinnati 13896 

Cities  Service  Oil  Co 14127 

Clark,  Prof.  J.  M 13698 

Cleveland Facing  13853,  13896,  13899,  J3900 

Colorado 13900,  14116 

Colorado  Fuel  and  Iron  Corporation 13900 

Columbia  Steel  Corporation 13749,  13900,  14101 

Commerce,  United  States  Department  of .   13914, 

13930-13932,  13941,  13960,  13963,  13973,  13979,  13983,  13987 

Commercial  and  Financial  Chronicle 13770 

"Comparative  Asscmblv  Costs  in  the  Manufacture  of  Pig  Iron" 13899 

Cone,  Frederick  M...-" 13931,  13941 

Congress  of  the  United  States 13672 

Continental  Can  Co 13898 

Continental  Oil  Co 14127-14128 

Cor-Ten 14116 

Costs : 

Cash 13600~lo602 

Operating,  analysis  of . 13666-13670 

Relationship  between,  and  sales 13802-1361 6 

United  States  Steel  Corporation's  analysis  of 13617-13631,  13695-13718 

Costs,  prices  and  demand,  relationship  between 13655-13665 

Court,  A.-  T 1 13990 

Cowles  Commission  for  Econorinic  Research 13587,  13604,  13650 

Crum,'W.  L 13941 

Currie,  Dr.  Langhhn 13640-13641,  13984,  14015 

Czechoslovakia 13S63 

Das  Deutsche  Ivartelbrect 13616 

deChazeau,  Dr.  Melvin 13615-13617,  13629,  13642,  13648-13652 

13654,  13661,  13663,  13670,  13672,  13732,  13740,  13907,  13918 
Demand  for  -tccl,  United  States  Steel  Corporation's  analvses  of..   13632-13648, 

13720-13741 

Discussion  of,  bv  Dr.  Theodore  Otte  Yntema 13732-13741 

Examination  of,  by  Dr.  Louis  lican 13720-13732 

Demand,  prices  and  costs,  relationship  between 13655-13665 

Der  Unlauten  Wettbewerg..- 1361(j 

Detroit 13896,  13899 

Dickinson,  Edward  T.,  Jr 13913,  13942,  13981,  13999,  14016,  14095,  14101 

Doblin,  Ernest  M 13913,  13942,  13981,  13999,  14016,  14095,  14101 

Dodge,  F.  W.,  Corporation . 13969,  13975 

Dubril,  S.  M : 13991 

Dun  &  Bradstreet,  Inc.    . 1398U 

Eastern  Railroads,  Public  Relations  committee  of 14014 

Econometric  Society 13898 

"Economics  of  Overhead  Costs,  Tiie"... 13698 

Edison  Electric  Institute 13967 

Electric  Overhead  Crane  Institute .    13973 

]•: urope -    .-- 13722 

Evaporated  Milk  Association. ^ 14018 

fJzekiel,  Dr.  Mordecai.    13617, 

13671,  13676,  13684,  13709-13710,  13730,  13739  13741 

Fabricant,  S 14009 

Fairless,  Benjamin  F _ . 13585.  13587 

Federal  Reserve  Bank  of  New  York . .    13970 

Federal  Reserve  Board 13659-13660,  13924.  13934,  13942.  13949,  13954- 

13955.  13957,  13962,  13969,  14001,  14013,  14027,  14029,  14032 

Board  of  Governors  of . 13935,  13963,  13965,  14013 

Division  of  Research  and  Statistics 14029 

"Federal  Reserve  Index  of  Indu.strial  Production". 13934-13935 

Federal  Trade  Conuni.Sfsion 13586,  13078,  13788,  14036  14038,  14080,  14127 

Ford  Motor  Co. 13898,13990 


INDEX  III 

Page 

Fordham  University 1 3650 

Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce,  United  States  Bureau  of 13966 

Foundry  Equipment  Manufacturers  Association 13973 

General  Motors  Corporation 13590, 

13733,  13898,  13915,  13963,  13982,  13987,  14059,  14087 

German  cartel  law 13616 

Germany 13863 

Goldenweiser,  F.  A 13935 

Government  of  the  United  States,. 13641-13642,  13645,  13659,  13670,  13688 

Great  Britain '. 13863 

Great  Lakes  Pipe  Line  Co 14127-14128 

Hance,  Dr.  Wendell  D 13983 

Hansen,  Dr.  Alvir 13963 

Harvard  School  of  Business . 13720 

Harvard  University 1 3693 

Harvard  University  Press 13700,  13908 

Haskins  and  Sells  Foundation 13698 

Hatfield, 13698 

Hauseman,  Henry —   14127 

Hawaii 1 13900 

Hitler,  Adolf 13645 

Holmes,  C.  A 14127 

Holmes,  Justice  Oliver  Wendell 13740 

Homer,  S.  L 13986,  13988 

Hosmer,  W.  A 13700 

Houston 13896 

Hydraulic  Institute 13973 

Indiana 13899 

Inland  Steel  Co 13903 

In  Memoriam  Senator  William  E.  Borah 13648 

Internal  Revenue,  United^ States  Bureau  of 13932-13933,  13941,  13961 

International  Harvester  Co 13898 

International  Tin  Research  and   Development  Council 14018, 

14020,  14024,  14026-14027 

Interstate  Commerce  Commission 13705, 

13716,  13969,  14003,  14005-14006,  14009,  14012,  14014  14016,  14127 

Iowa 13899 

"Iron  Age" 13033, 

13695-13696,  13717,  13794,  13797-13799,  13801-13803,  13807-13809, 
13814-13815,  13818,  13836,  13863,  13884-13885,  13888,  13890,  13895, 
13924,  13928,  13940,  13949,  13967,  13974-13976,  13978-13981,  13985, 
13992-13995,  13997,  14007-14009,  14011-14012,  14019-14020,  14029- 
14030,  14096-14102,  14104,  14120. 

''Iron  and  Steel  and  Their  Products" 13910 

Iron  and  Steel  Works  Directory 13903 

Ironton,  Utah . 13900 

Japan         ..• 13722,13863 

"Jobs  for  All" . - 13677 

Jones  &  Laughlin  Steel  Corpc.ttion 13903 

Justice,  DepartmeAt  of 13616,  13671,  13838,  13840-13842,  13844-13845 

Kentucky ' 13899 

Kuhns,  P.  H . 14127 

Kuznets,  Simon 13932,  13941,  13960,  13963,  13983,  13987,  13996 

Labor  Statistics,  United  States  Bureau  of 13668,  13882-13883,  13966, 

13978,  13990,  14020,  14022,  14030,  14044,  14046,  14052-14053 

Labor,  United  States  Department  of 13731,  14020,  14030 

Lackawanna Facing  13833 

Lake  Erie 13899-13900 

Lake  Michigan 13899 

Lake  Superior.,.-. 13899,  14122 

Lewis,  Harold  Gregg . . 13049-13650, 

13738,  13913,  13942,  13981,  13999,  1401-6,  14095,  14101 

Lippert,  T.  W 13695-13696,  13712,  14120 

Los  Angeles..--' 13896,  13900 

Louisiana 14116 

Manlove,  G.  H . 13940 

Maryland  State  Planniig  Commip^jion 13900 


IW  INDEX 

Page 

McGraw-Hill  Book  Co 13617,  13907,  13918 

Midcontincnt  Petroleum  Corporation 14127 

Miller,  Governor  Nathan 13586 

Mills,  Dr.  Frederick  C 13647,  13685,  13998 

Milwaukee 13896 

Minnesota 13899 

Moreland,  Harry 14 127-14 1 28 

Moody's  Industrials 1376S 

Moore,  Henry  L 13698,  13913 

Mosak,  Jacob  L 13913,  13942,  13981,  13999,  14016,  14095,  14101 

Mudgett,  B.  D 13937,  13940 

Musgrave,  C.  R.-- 14127 

Nathan,  Robert  R 13930-13931,  13941,  13963,  13966 

National  Association  of  Cost  Accountants 13910-13911 

National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research 13899, 

13932,  13941,  13960,  13963,  13983,  13994,  13996,  13998,  14009 

National  Canners  Association 14018-14020 

National  City  Bank,  New  York :___    13933 

National  Electrical  Manufacturers'  Association 13967,  13973 

National  Income  and  Capital  Formation 13932,  13941,  13960,  13963 

National  Industiial  Conference  Board  Index 13786, 

13888,  13932,  13941,  13963-13964,  13966,  13987 

National  Industrial  Recovery  Act 14122 

National  Machine  Tool  Builders  Association 13973 

National  research  project,  W.  P.  A 13937 

National  Resources  Committee 13725,   13913. 

14000-14022,  14011,  14013,  14020,  14022,  14027,  14029-14031 

National  Steel  Corporation 13674,  13903 

National  Tube  Co 14106 

Newark 13896 

New  Jersey 1 3900 

New  York'. 13896,  13911,  13915,  13918,  13996 

New  York  Stock  Exchange 13770-13771 

N.  R.  A 13694,  13948 

O'Day,  J.  M 14127 

Ohio_.-. : 13896,  13899,  13900 

Oil  Well  Supply  Co J 13749 

Olds,  Irving  S . :...   13585,  13650 

Organization  Service  Corporation 13973 

Orvis,  Eugene . 1 41 27-14 128 

Pennsylvania 13900 

Persons,  Dr.  Warren 13663 

Philadelphia 13896,  13900 

Phillips  Petroleum  Co 14127 

Philo  Verlag  und  Buchhandlung  G.  M.  B.  G 13616 

Pittsburgh 13797,  13803,  13808,  Facing  13833,  13834 

13837,  13887,  13896,  13899,  13900,  13940,  13976,  14030.  14117 

Plymouth  Motor  Corporation 13990 

President  of  the  United  States 1 401 4 

Price  reductions,  effects  of . . . J 13597-13606 

Prices: 

High,  failure  of  to  produce  business 13686-13688 

Reduced,  through  concerted  action  of  producers,  efTect  of 136SS-13603 

Prices,  demand  and  co.st'^,  relation.'ihip  between.. 13655-13665 

Pure  Oil  Co 14127 

"Railway  Age" . 13973,  14007 

Rechtsanwalt  am  Landgericht 13616 

Republic  Steel  Co 13900,  13903 

Roe,  H.  W    ....      ... 14127 

Rollmann  &  Maver ..    i:^616 

Hoos,  C.  F ". 13589,  13733,  13915-13916,  13922. 

13941,  13963,  13967.  13982,  13986-13991,  13993,  14059.  140S7 

Roosevelt,  President  F.  D 14003.  14005 

Russia 13863 

Sales,  relationship  between,  and  costs -.. 13602-13616 

vSanders, 1369.S 


INDEX  V 

Page 

San  Francisco 13896,  13900 

Schultz,  Henry 13917,  13925,  14020 

Securities  and  Exchange  Commission 13700.  13702,  13705,  13984,  14040 

Segal,  Mandal  R 13913,  13942,  13981,  13999,  14016,  14095,  14101 

Sherman  Act 13078 

Silver  Purchase  Act 13947 

Sinclair  Refining  Co 14127 

Skelly  Oil  Co . 14127 

SiniondsSaw  &  Steel  Co ---   13898 

Skemp,  R 14026 

Social  Science  Research  Council 13937 

Social  Security  Act - 13930 

Social  Security  taxes 13600-13601,  13953-13954,  14044,  14057,  14083,  14122 

Spanish  Civil  War 13948 

Splawn,  Commissioner  M.  W 14005 

Sprague,  Prof.  O.  M.  W 13693 

St.  Louis 13896 

Statistical  Yearbook 14020 

Standard  Statistics  Co.,  Inc . 13909,  13965,  13970,  13980 

Standard  Trade  and  Securities 13909 

"Statistical  Investigation  in  the  Demand  for  Iron  and  Steel" 13913 

"Statistical  Yearbook" 14020,  14024 

Steel  Workers  Organizing  Committee 13953 

Stratton, 13907,  13918 

Stewart.  R .  E 14128 

Studies,  United  States  Steel  Corporation: 

Analyses,    demand.     See    Demand    for    steel.    United    States    Steel 
Corporation's  analyses  of. 

Summary  and  description  of ^ 13587-13616 

Sweezv,  Paul  M 13918 

Taitel",  Martin        13622,  13671,  13694,  13709-13712,  13718,  13740-13741 

Tariff  Commission,  United  States 13644,  13660 

Tenn(>s.-^ee  Coal,  Iron  and  Railroad  Co 13900,  13910,  14106 

Terborgh,  George 13963,  14026 

Texas-!---,--    - 14116 

Texas  Corporation,  The 14127 

Timken  Roller  Bearing  Co.,  Inc 13898 

Topeka  &  Santa  Fe  Railroad  Co 13898 

Treasury,  United  States  Department  of 13033,  13941,  13961,  14025 

United  States  Steel  Corporation 1 3585-13587, 

13595-13600,  13603-13604,  13606-13615,  13617-13618,  13620, 
13622-13627,  13629,  13630-13633,  13636,  13638-13639,  13644, 
13649-13651,  13654,  13658,  13661,  13666,  13667,  13670,  13672- 
13673j  13676,  13679,  13683-13685,  13687-13688,  13690-13691, 
13G93,  13695,  13697,  13699-13700,  13702-13705,  13707-13709, 
13711,  13713-13715,  13717,  13720,  13722,  13724,  13728-13731, 
13740,  13746-13747,  13751-137.57,  137.59,  13761-13773,  13786- 
13788,  13796-13798,  13800,  13802,  13804-13806,  13821,  13834- 
13836,  13848-13849,  13851,  138.53.  13857,  13859-13860,  13868- 
13871,  13874,  13878,  13880-13881,  138S3-13889,  13891-13896, 
1.3899-13900,  13903,  13906,  13910,  13913,  13929,  13937-13939, 
13942,  13949-13950.  139.53,  13055,  13958.  13976,  1397S,  13981, 
13997-13999.  14007,  14016,-  14019,  14029,  14032-14038,  14058- 
U059,  14061-14065,  14068,  14073-14074.  14080.  14082-14095, 
14098,  14101.  14106,  14110,  14114,  14116,  14121-14123. 
Analytics  of: 

Cost  in  relatio!!  to  volume 13617-13631 

Demand  for  steel 13632-13648,  1 3720-13741 

Special  Economic  Research  Section  of 13913,  13981,  13999,  14016 

Studies  made  bv.     See  Studies,  United  States  Steel  Corporation. 

University  of  Chicago 13587,13601.   136.50,   13694,   13732,  "13738, 

13913, 13942,  i3981,  13999,  14016,  14032,  14082,  14095,  14101. 

University  of  Pittsburgh 13617 

University  of  Rochester ^ 13720 

Univeroitv  of  Virginia -   13617 

U.  S.  S.  R 1386.3 


VI  INDEX 

Page 
Utah 13900 

Vacuum  Cleaners'  Association 13967 

Vandergrift  mill 12808,  13834 

von  Szeliski,  Victor 13589,   13733,'  13915-13916,  13922,  13941, 

13963,  13982,   13986-13991,   13993,  14059,  14087 

Walker,  C.  A.  L 14128 

West  Virginia 13899-13900 

Wliceling  Steel  Corporation 13903 

White  &  Case. 13650 

White,  Ed  ward . 1 3933 

White,  Hugh  E 13586 

Whitman,  Roswell,  H 13913 

Winn,  A.  F . 14127 

Winn,  O'Kay I  -  -  - : 14128 

Wisconsin 13833 

Wooden,  Walter  B.... . 13586,  13616,  13643 

Woodworking  Machinery  Manufacturers  Association 13973 

Work  Projects  Administration „.   13694 

Works  Progress  Administration -^.. _    13937,  139.41,  14020 

Division  of  Social  Research ,---^_ 14020 

World  War  I 13678,  13680,  14000 

Worthing,  Miss  M.  W ' 13895, 

13899,  13913,   13918,   13938,  13942,  13981,   13997.  13999,   14007. 
14012,   14010,   14019,   14029,  14095,  14101 

Wright,  C.  E 139-!0.  13981 

Yntcma,  Dwight  B 13913,  13942.  13981,  130Q9,  14016.  14095.  14101 

Yntema,  Dr.  Theodore  Ottc 13.586- 

13587,  13604,  13615,  13617,  13620-13622,  13626.  13628,  13630- 
13635,  13637-13640,  13642-13644,  13648-13649,  13652  13654, 
13659-13660,  13662-13663,  13075,  13682,  13087,  13697,  13709, 
13712-137M,  13717-13718,  13732,  13740-13741,  13913,  13942, 
13981,  13999,  14016,  14032.  14082,  14095,  14101 
Discussion  by  of  United  States  Steel  Corporation  demaiid  analvses---    13732- 

13741 
Youngstown  Sheet  &  Tube  Co ..   13674.  13903 


BOSTON 


PUBUCUBBABV 


k