Skip to main content

Full text of "Michigan manual of forestry ;"

See other formats


UC-NRLF 


B  3  sag  am 


x .  - 1'  01  esuy  •  -Mui 


73 

'2  • 

.  FOREST  VALUATION, 


VOLUME  II 

OF 


Michigan  Manual  of  Forestry 


BY 

FILIBERT  ROTH 

1916    )/ 


PUBLISHED  BY  THE  AUTHOR 
ANN  ARBOR,  MICHIGAN 


I/ 

Ni   * 


COPYRIGHT,  1916 
BY  FII^IB^RT  ROTH 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 

FOREST  VALUATION. 

PAGE; 

I.  INTRODUCTION    i 

A.  Literature    I 

B.  Scope  and  Application 2 

1 .  General    2 

2.  Valuation  and  Statics 3 

3.  Application 4 

C.  History  of  Valuation 7 

II.  ARITHMETIC  OF  FOREST  VALUATION 10 

a.  General    10 

b.  Prolongation,  Discount  and  Rate n 

c.  Summation  of   Series 1 1 

d.  Present  Value  of  Series 13 

e.  Series  of  Periodic  Payments 14 

f .  Sum  of  Infinite  Series 15 

g.  Change  of  Periodic  to  Yearly  Payments 17 

h.    Table  of   Formulae 17 

III.  APPLICATION  OF  VALUATION 19 

A.  Timber  Crop,  its  Nature  and  Value 19 

B.  Risk  in  Forestry .  22 

C.  Interest  Rate  in  Forestry 24 

D.  Valuation  of  Land  or  Soil 29 

a.  Cost,  Sale — Income  Value 29 

b.  Cost  and  Sale — Value  of  Forest  Land  in  United 

States    31 

c.  Income  Value  of  Land  in  Forestry 32 

E.  Valuation  of  Soil  and  Statics 36 

a.  Relation  of  Se  and  its  Factors 36 

b.  Values  of  Factors  of   Se  and  Variation  in  these 

Factors   38 

1.  The  Final  Yield  or  Yr 38 

2.  Thinnings    46 

3.  Cost  of  Reproduction,  c 48 

4.  Current  Expenses,  e 51 

5.  Rotation,   r 54 

6.  Interest  Rate,  p 55 

333963 


IV  FOREST  VALUATION 

c.  Actual  Values  of  Se 56 

d.  Appreciation  of  Calculation  of  Se 57 

e.  Se  of  the  Copice  Woods '.  .  .  .  60 

f.  Se  in  the  Selection  Forest. 60 

F.  Value  of  Stand  or  Growing  Stock  in  Even-aged  Stand.  60 

a.  Sale  Value  of  Growing  Stock 61 

b.  Cost  Value  of  Growing  Stock 61 

c.  Expectation  Value  of  Growing  Stock.  .  .  .  , 63 

d.  Which  Value  to  Use 64 

e.  Value  of  Land  and  Growing  Stock  together 65 

G.  Value   of    Growing    Stock   of    Regulated   or    Normal 

Forest 65 

a.  The  Regulated  Forest 66 

b.  Expectation  Value  of  Growing  Stock  of  Regulated 

Normal  Forest 66 

€.    Cost    Value   of    Growing   Stock   in   Regulated   or 

Normal  Forest    70 

H.    Value  of  Growing  Stock  in  the  All-aged  Forest 70 

a.  In  the  Regulated  Forest 70 

b.  In  the  Irregular  Forest.  .  . 72 

IV.  RELATION  OF  CAPITAL  AND  INCOME:  IN  FORESTRY 73 

a;    Nature  of  Income  and  Profit  in  Forestry.  . 73 

b.  Interest  made  by  the  Forest 75 

1.  Interest   made   by   a   Single    Stand   of    Even-aged 

Forest    75 

a.  During  a  Short  Period 76 

b.  During  an  Entire  Rotation 78 

2.  Rate  of  Interest  made  by  a  Regulated  Forest 79 

3.  Rate  of  Interest  made  in  Forestry  when  starting 

with  Bare  Land  as  Capital 81 

c.  Comparison  of  Properties  with  Yearly  and  with  Inter- 

mittent or  Periodic  Income 82 

V.  ROTATION 85 

a.  Rotation  for  Largest  Income 85 

b.  Rotation  for  Largest  Net  Rental  or  Highest  Rate  of 

Interest    87 

VI.  VALUE  OF  STUMPAGE  89 

A.  Cost  Value  of  Stumpage 89 

B.  Sale  Value  of  Stumpage 90 

C.  Expectation  Value  of  Stumpage 96 


otf  CONTENTS  v 

VII.  DAMAGE  IN  TIMBER  98 

a.  Shade  Tree   98 

b.  Young  Plantation  of  Forest  Trees 99 

c.  Older  Plantations 99 

d.  Ordinary  Stand  in  Wild  Woods 99 

e.  Young  Stands  of  Wild  Woods 101 

f.  The   Lumberman's   Case 102 

VIII.  TAXATION  otf  FORESTS 105 

a.  Nature  of  Taxation 105 

b.  Assessment  and   Rate 105 

c.  Forest  Tax  Impersonal 108 

d.  Forest  Taxation  in  Europe 108 

e.  Forest  Taxation  in  the  United  States 112 

f.  Recent  Reforms  in  Forest  Taxation 114 

g.  Basis  of  New  Tax  Laws • 115 

h.    Future  in  Forest  Taxation 119 

IX.  FIRE  INSURANCE  IN  FORESTRY 122 

X.  RIGHT  USE  OF  LAND 128 

a.  Nature  of  Land .- 128 

b.  Classification  of  Lands 128 

c.  Factors  affecting  the  Use  of  Land 128 

d.  Use  of  Lands  in  the  Old  World 130 

e.  Land  Conditions  in  the  United  States 131 

f.  Agricultural  Use 131 

g.  Income  from  Land 133 

1.  Income  from  Farm  Lands.  . 135 

2.  Income   from   Forests 138 

3.  Income   from   Range 140 

APPENDIX    , 143 

A.  Normal  Yield  Tables   143 

B.  Tables  for  Prolongation  and  Discount 157 

C.  Suggestions  for  Problems  for  School  use 167 


FOREST  VALUATION 


I.    INTRODUCTION 

A.     LITERATURE. 

Endres,  Dr.  Max.  Lehrbuch  der  Waldwertrechnung  und 
Forststatik,  2nd  ed.  1911,  published  by  Julius  Springer,  Berlin; 
308  pp. 

Dr.  Endres  is  Professor  of  Forestry  at  the  University  of 
Miinchen,  and  author  of  the  great  "Forst  Politik,"  one  of  the  most 
instructive  books  in  forestry  literature.  On  pages  1-4  is  given  a  full 
list  of  the  literature  of  the  subject.  In  addition  the  literature  and 
historic  facts  of  interest  are  added  to  all  important  points  in  the 
treatise.  An  excellent  set  of  tables  of  compound  interest,  etc.,  forms 
the  appendix.  As  Dr.  Endres  says  (p.  2),  "Scientific  forest  valuation 
is  based  on  the  labors  of  Faustman,  Pressler  and  Gustav  Heyer," 
and  so  it  is  but  natural  that  this  excellent  and  most  complete  treatise 
should  follow  the  works  of  these  three  great  men  and  represent 
what  is  accepted  today  as  correct  and  scientific  in  forest  valuation. 

Stoetzer,  Dr.  H.  Waldwertrechnung  und  Forstliche  Statik, 
Frankfurt,  1894 ;  4th  ed.  1908. 

Dr.  Stoetzer's  work  as  author,  teacher  and  administrator,  and 
also  as  editor  of  the  great  Handbuch,  is  well  known.  In  Valuation 
and  Statics  he  has  stood  and  stands  today  one  of  the  foremost 
authorities. 

Martin,  Dr.  H.  Die  Forstliche  Statik,  Berlin,  1905,  Julius 
Springer,  361  pp. 

Dr.  Martin  is  Professor  of  Forestry  at  Tharandt,  formerly  at 
Eberswalde,  author  of  "Forsteinrichtung,"  a  prolific  writer,  well 
known  teacher  and  recognized  authority.  This  book  is  entirely  de- 
voted to  Statics  of  Forestry;  its  position  is  defined  in  the  sentence 
(p.  22),  "As  to  the  system  and  contents  of  this  book,  the  author 
closely  follows  Hundeshagen."  In  his  introduction,  one  of  the  most 
interesting  and  instructive  chapters  ever  published  on  Forest  Valua- 
tion and  Statics,  he  discusses  the  historic  development  and  points 
out  the  fact  that  the  useful  study  of  Statics  was  opposed  in  practice 


2*'.  ,      FOREST  VALUATION 

chiefly  because  the  writers  clung  too  much  to  mathematics  and 
formulae.  The  chapter,  ''Choice  between  agriculture  and  forestry 
in  the  use  of  land,"  to  which  thirty-five  per  cent  of  the  book  is 
devoted  is  one  of  the  best  discussions  of  this  subject  and  particularly 
interesting  at  the  present  time  to  students  of  forestry  and  economics 
in  the  United  States. 

Schlich,  Dr.  W.  Manual  of  Forestry,  vol.  Ill,  1895,  4th 
ed.  1911. 

A  brief  chapter,  fifty-nine  pages  in  the  first  edition,  following 
closely  the  treatment  by  German  authors. 

Schenck,  Dr.  C.  A.  Forest  Finance,  published  by  Dr.  Schenck, 
Biltmore,  N.  C.,  1909. 

Chapman,  H.  H.  Forest  Valuation,  Wiley  &  Sons,  New  York, 
1915;  310  pp. 

Professor  Chapman  treats  the  subject  from  the  American  stand- 
point, and  adds  a  number  of  topics  not  ordinarily  treated  in  this 
connection,  particularly,  Appraisal  of  damages;  Forest  taxation; 
Stumpage  values ;  Future  values  of  forest  products,  and  Risks. 
Convenient  tables  of  the  various  formulae,  compound  interest  values 
and  logarithms  form  the  appendix. 

Fernow,  Dr.  B.  E.     Forest  Economics  and  Forest  History. 

Dr.  Fernow,  now  Professor  of  Forestry  at  Toronto  University, 
himself  a  student  of  Gustav  Heyer,  points  out  the  historic  develop- 
ment and  the  application  of  Forest  Valuation  and  Statics. 


B.     SCOPE  AND  APPLICATION  OF  FOREST 
VALUATION  AND  STATICS. 

i.     General. 

In  Forestry,  just  as  in  farming  and  other  lines  of  business, 
nearly  every  transaction  involves  expense  and  income  and  demands 
judgment  of  values.  If  a  piece  of  land,  the  timber  on  the  land,  or 
a  piece  of  forest  (land  and  timber  together)  is  bought,  sold,  rented, 
leased,  or  in  any  way  contracted  for,  the  first  question  concerns  the 
value  of  the  property  under  consideration.  If  a  forester  plants  an 
acre  of  land  to  forest  trees  the  owner  wants  to  know  what  such 
work  should  cost  and  if  under  the  particular,  conditions  it  may  be 
expected  to  pay.  Since  it  may  take  the  crop  fifty  or  more  years  to 
grow  to  useful  size,  the  question  as  to  whether  it  will  pay  or  not 
involves  the  future  and  the  owner  must  of  necessity  have  faith  in 
certain  premises.  He  must  believe  that  the  trees  will  grow  and 


VALUATION  AND  STATICS  3 

thrive  on  the  particular  site,  that  a  certain  amount  of  expense  will 
suffice  to  care  for  them,  that  they  will  reach  a  useful  size  in  a  cer- 
tain time,  and  finally,  that  they  will  have  a  definite  value  when  cut. 
If  he  has  no  faith  in  any  of  these  premises  it  is  an  inexcusable 
"gamble"  for  him  to  plant  the  trees.  But  to  have  faith  in  business 
premises  is  not  peculiar  to  forestry ;  a  man  buying  a  farm  believes 
that  the  land  will  produce  certain  crops,  produce  them  in  ten  or 
twenty  years  just  as  now,  and  that  the  crops  have  a  certain  value, 
justifying  his  labor  and  expense.  Some  years  a  dry  season,  frost, 
hail  or  insects  destroy  most  of  his  crops,  but  in  the  long  run  he  main- 
tains a  successful  average. 

2.     Valuation  and  Statics. 

When  the  buyer  estimates  and  examines  a  stand  of  timber 
which  he  intends  to  cut  over  at  once,  he  merely  determines  the 
value  for  immediate  use  and  the  work  is  one  of  simple  forest 
valuation. 

When  a  lumberman  buys  a  body  of  timber  with  a  view  of 
supplying  his  business  for  the  next  twenty  years,  the  case  is  less 
simple.  He  has  to  reckon  with  the  future  and  with  many  uncer- 
tainties; the  timber  may  be  old  and  become  defective  before  he  is 
ready  to  cut ;  fire  and  insects  may  destroy ;  certain  railway  develop- 
ments which  he  expects  may  not  take  place ;  the  prices  of  timber  may 
not  advance;  taxes,  interest,  or  other  expense  may  eat  up  all  the 
expected  profits.  It  is  a  case  of  nice  judgment  in  which  the  differ- 
ent factors  and  conditions  are  estimated,  if  possible,  in  money  value 
and  balanced  to  arrive  at  a  final  result.  It  is  a  case  of  weighing 
various  conditions;  weighing  effort  and  expense  against  expected 
results.  It  is  no  longer  simple  valuation,  but  complex  valuation 
with  a  heavy  proportion  of  statics,  of  the  science  and  art  of  weigh- 
ing cause  and  effect  in  our  case,  costs  and  results. 

When  the  owner  of  a  piece  of  land  decides  to  change  from 
farm  crop  to  forest,  he  does  so  because  he  has  weighed  the  advan- 
tages and  disadvantages  of  both  lines  and  found  that  the  forest 
will  pay  better.  This  weighing  is  Forest  Statics.  The  "pay  better" 
need  not  be  in  money  at  all. 

When  a  forester  decides  to  give  up  natural  reproduction  and 
plant  five  year  transplants  of  spruce,  he  does,  or  should  do  this  only 
after  careful  weighing  or  calculation.  His  calculation  should  show 
clearly  that  he  may  expect  a  material  gain  by  going  to  this  greater 
expense  of  planting.  In  making  his  calculation  he- starts  with  the 
cost  of  planting.  This  he  knows  from  experience.  He  figures  on 


4  FOREST  VALUATION 

a  more  even  stand,  more  rapid  growth,  earlier  thinnings,  more  in- 
come from  thinning  and  on  an  earlier  final  cut,  saving  him  several 
years  waiting,  use  of  the  land  and  interest  on  the  value  of  the  stand. 
Aside  from  the  planting,  all  seems  guess  work.  But  this  is  not  the 
case;  he  has  the.  experience  of  centuries,  of  thousands  of  men,  of 
many  thousand  acres  of  timber  to  guide  him.  He  has  faith  in  this 
experience  and  decides  to  plant.  His  process  of  weighing  possi- 
bilities is  Forest  Statics.  It  computes  extra  costs  and  forecasts 
extra  results. 

It  is  clear  that  Forest  Valuation  and  Forest  Statics  are  not 
sharply  separated,  that  in  most  cases  of  valuation  more  or  less 
statics  is  involved  and  for  this  reason  the  two  are  generally  treated 
together  in  forestry,  just  as  in  other  forms  of  valuation. 

In  the  above  cases  the  lumberman  or  the  forester  might  prefer 
not  to  go  through  any  tedious  process  of  reasoning,  analysis  or 
calculation,  and  simply  "jump  at"  the  conclusion  that  he  could-pay 
ten  dollars  per  acre  for  the  timber,  or  in  the  case  of  the  forester 
that  he  could  better  afford  to  plant  than  to  go  on  with  natural  repro- 
duction. No  doubt  much  of  this  is  done.  Some  gifted  or  lucky  men 
succeed,  most  men  lose.  The  gifted  man  has  his  own  short  method 
and  his  results  are  correct  in  proportion  as  he  is  clever.  The  aver- 
age man  can  not  and  does  not  jump  at  conclusions  or  guess  results 
if  he  can  avoid  it.  And  it  is  to  help  the  average  man  analyze  a  given 
case,  weigh  the  various  factors  and  combine  them  in  a  scientific 
and  effective  manner  that  modern  forest  valuation  was  developed. 
The  importance  of  this  development  in  forestry  is  emphasized  by 
the  fact  that  the  forester  commonly  deals  with  large  properties,  not 
his  own,  where  it  becomes  necessary  to  place  the  case  before  the 
owner  or  his  agent  in  a  perfectly  clear  and  convincing  form.  At 
such  a  time  every  item  must  be  clearly  stated  in  a  form  capable  of 
detailed  discussion,  the  methods  of  analysis  and  calculation  must 
be  explained  and  stand  the  test  of  examination  and  trial. 

3.     Application  of  Valuation  and  Statics. 

As  in  every  other  business,  so  in  forestry,  the  work  of  valua- 
tion or  the  determination  of  cost  or  value  of  property  (land,  timber, 
etc.,)  or  of  operations  (planting,  thinning,  protection,  logging,  etc.,) 
follows  every  line  of  work  and  is  always  in  evidence.  For  example 
its  application  in  a  few  of  the  most  important  branches  of  forest 
business : 

i.  In  purchase,  sale  and  exchange  of  property,  such  as  land 
timber,  or  forest  (land  and  timber  together)  the  necessity  of  ascer- 


APPU CATION  Otf  VALUATION  5 

taining  the  value  of  the  property  bought  or  sold  is  evident.  This 
kind  of  work  in  the  United  States  at  the  present  time  is  very  im- 
portant and  will  be  more  important  in  the  future  than  it  has  been 
in  the  past.  The  mere  cruise  for  merchantable  timber  will  no  longer 
satisfy  men  buying  and  selling  forest  properties.  To  sell  a  forest 
for  the  value  of  the  merchantable  stuff  alone  is  equivalent  to  giving 
away  over  half  the  value  in  many  localities  and  this  condition  is 
rapidly  extending. 

2.  Holding  of  timber  for  future  use  is  a  common  practice 
among  lumbermen.     In  buying  for  ten  or  twenty  years  it  is  neces- 
sary to  compute  expenses,  taxes,  interest,  protection,  probable  losses, 
and  it  requires  an  estimate  or  forecast  of  the  price  which  may  be 
obtained  at  the  end  of  the  period  or  at  the  time  of  cutting.    Taxes 
and  interest  together  with  other  current  expenses  come  every  year 
and  accumulate  with  compound  interest;  the  final  value  must  be 
discounted  to  the  present  time.    There  is  a  right  way  of  doing  this 
and  many  wrong  ways  and  some  of  our  lumbermen  in  the  Lake 
Region  and  elsewhere  are  finding  today  that  it  is  not  always  easy 
to  make  a  state  tax  commission  see  the  right  way  of  computing  the 
true  value  of  a  lot  of  stumpage  which  can  not  possibly  be  cut  "before 
ten  or  twenty  years. 

3.  Timber  contracts,  leases,  rights  of  way.  etc.,  are  common 
and  necessary.    A  long  time  contract  for  hemlock  in  a  hemlock  and 
hardwood  forest  may  become  a  very  difficult  and  troublesome  affair. 
To  draw  up  such  a  contract  requires  a  forester's  judgment;  to  settle 
it  equitably  involves  forest  valuation  and  statics. 

4.  Damage  in  timber,  usually  trespass  or  fire,  is  very  com- 
mon.    In  the  past  it  was  impossible  for  the  courts  to  administer 
justice:  these  cases  were  among  the  most  unsatisfactory;  the  evi- 
dence was  neither  clear  nor  convincing,  the  methods  of  calculation 
could  not  be  explained,  they  were  never  agreed  upon ;  it  was  a  battle 
of   unproved   assertion   backed   by   a   pretence   of   experience   and 
authority.    As  a  result  the  courts  granted  nothing  beyond  a  simple 
provable  loss  of  material  actually  saleable  at  the  time  of  destruction. 
Since  modern  forest  valuation  has  found  its  way  into  the  woods 
business  this  situation  has  been  relieved  very  materially  and  the 
courts  are  glad  to  be  able  to  grant  real  justice  based  upon  an  orderly, 
intelligent  method  of  determining  the  values.     In  fact  the  applica- 
tion of  modern  forest  valuation  in  the  United  States  had  its  first 
tests  in  damage  cases. 

5.  Taxation   requires   assessment   of   the   true  value   of   the 
property.     As  long  as  it  was  a  fight  with  local  assessors  the  old 


6  FOREST  VALUATION 

methods  alone  were  effective.  Since  the  state  tax  commission  takes 
a  hand  in  the  assessment  it  becomes  necessary  to  apply  forest  valua- 
tion to  show  that  if  hemlock  is  worth  five  dollars  per  M.  feet  on  the 
stump  for  immediate  use  that  the  stuff  to  be  cut  in  ten  years  from 
now  is  not  worth  five  dollars  unless  it  doubles  in  value  during  the 
ten  years,  which  it  has  not  done  in  the  last  ten  years  and  will  not  in 
the  next.  Similarly  in  our  efforts  at  tax  reform.  Several  states, 
notably  Pennsylvania,  New  York,  Massachusetts  and  Connecticut 
have  initiated  change  of  laws  regarding  taxation  of  forest  property. 
In  all  cases  a  "yield  tax"  was  introduced  and  the  taxation  of  the 
land  was  modified.  But  what  is  a  reasonable  tax  on  stumpage?  Is 
it  ten  per  cent  as  in  Pennsylvania,  or  six  per  cent  as  in  Massachusetts 
and  what  basis  has  either  state  for  its  estimate?  Guessing  and 
juggling  a  few  figures  will  not  give  any  permanent,  satisfactory 
relief ;  it  will  require  modern  forest  valuation  to  supply  a  basis. 

6.  The  right  use  of  land  is  one  of  the  most  important  economic 
questions  in  two-thirds  of  the  United  States.  Is  it  wise  to  try  to  farm 
all  lands  in  Michigan,  New  York  and  Pennsylvania ;  should  part  be 
devoted  to  forest  and  if  so  what  part,  in  what  amount;  what  will 
be  the  economic  result  if  these  lands  are  used  to  raise  timber;  how 
may  we  determine  which  of  the  two,  forest  or  field  should  have 
preference  in  a  given  case  ?    Booster  oratory  or  decision  by  the  man 
in  the  office  may  deceive  some  people  for  a  time  but  it  will  lead  to 
great  losses  in  the  end.     Pennsylvania,  the  Lake  Region  and  other 
districts  today  have  millions  of  acres  of  idle,  unused  lands  entailing 
a  loss  of  millions  of  dollars.     The  chief  obstacle  to  any  improve- 
ment in  this  situation  is  the  land  boomer  and  his  friends  who  con- 
tinue to  convince  the  legislatures  that  all  land  is  farm  land.    The  loss 
is  great  and  has  accumulated  for  years.    Nothing  but  the  application 
of  sound  methods  of  valuation  and  the  recognition  of  this  valuation 
by  the  legislatures  will  prepare  for  the  remedy  and  change  great 
money  loss  to  income  for  the  people. 

7.  The  Management  of  the  forest  is  and  must  always  be  the 
most  important  subject  of  forest  valuation  and  statics.     As  stated 
before,  every  time  an  acre  of  land  is  planted  to  trees  the  question 
arises — does  it  pay — should  a  different  kind  of  tree,  cheaper  plant 
stock,  cheaper  methods  of  planting  be  used.    Later  on — does  it  pay 
to  thin,  should  the  thinning  be  light  or  heavy,  and  how  often  can  we 
afford  to  thin  in  this  stand.    All  along  there  is  expense  for  protec- 
tion— should  it  be  cheap,  less  than  five  cents  per  acre,  will  it  pay  to 
go  as  high  as  ten  cents,  is  it  better  to  use  many  men  or  depend  on 
outfit,  etc.     In  the  end  comes  the  question — is  it  more  profitable  to 


HISTORY  OF  VALUATION  7 

cut  the  stuff  at  the  age  of  fifty,  eighty  or  a  hundred  years.  These 
and  many  other  questions  must  be  studied  and  answered  for  each 
stand,  for  each  neighborhood,  not  merely  once  but  repeatedly  because 
the  answer  varies  with  the  premises,  with  success  of  silviculture, 
market,  transportation,  cost  of  logging,  labor  in  general,  and  many 
other  conditions.  It  is  evident  that  in  management  the.  wrork  of 
valuation  is  largely  a  matter  of  weighing  or  statics,  though  a  great 
deal  of  simple  valuation  also  enters.  Every  year  dozens  of  stands 
must  be  estimated  and  millions  of  feet  of  timber  appraised  as  to 
their  proper  stumpage  value. 


C.     HISTORY. 

Forest  valuation  is  old.  Timber  was  an  object  of  traffic  with 
the  ancients,  and  traffic  is  unthinkable  without  valuation  or  the 
setting  of  a  price  on  the  object  bought  or  sold.  When  timber  was 
shipped  or  rafted,  forests  sold  or  exchanged,  or  mortgaged  as  is 
recorded  as  early  as  the  days  of  Charlemagne,  an  important  part  of 
the  transaction  was  the  determination  of  the  value  of  the  forest  or 
timber. 

Even  the  more  modern  conception  of  forest  valuation  the  com- 
parison of  the  growing  stock  to  a  capital  increasing  at  a  certain  per 
cent,  the  influence  of  the  rotation  or  long  interval  between  planting 
and  harvest,  and  finally  the  application  of  an  orderly  mathematical 
analysis  to  discover  the  proper  rotation  and  to  compare  different 
kinds  of  forest,  beech,  spruce,  etc.,  date  back  one  hundred  and  fifty 
years  and  more. 

According  to  Endres  (p.  183)  the  Forest  Order  of  the  princi- 
pality of  Neuburg,  Bavaria,  of  the  year  1577  makes  it  clear  that  the 
yield  from  the  forest  is  in  the  nature  of  interest  on  a  capital  and 
that  the  person  in  possession  has  no  right  to  cut  more  than  the 
growth  or  proper  yield,  being  entitled  only  to  the  interest. 

As  early  as  1623  the  English  economist  Culpepper  explained 
that  the  forest  could  not  produce  a  large  interest  rate.  In  1721 
Reaumur  pointed  out  that  too  long  a  rotation  meant  real  money 
loss,  and  in  1742  Buffon  in  his  "Memoirs  sur  la  culture  des  forets" 
discussed  the  same  subject  and  pointed  out  the  accumulation  of  ex- 
penses in  growing  a  forest  crop. 

In  1764  the  great  von  Zanthier,  first  to  establish  a  "Meister- 
schule"  for  foresters,  used  compound  interest  calculations  in  forest 
valuation ;  worked  out  a  comparison  for  different  rotations  in 
beech,  a  comparison  of  beech,  spruce  and  oak  in  which  all  expenses 


8  FOREST  VALUATION 

are  prolonged  to  the  end  of  the  rotation.  He  also  prepared  the  first 
money  yield  tables.  Endres  says  of  these  calculations  that  they 
were  satisfactory  (zweckentsprechend)  so  that  we  have  here  a 
perfectly  up-to-date  piece  of  valuation  and  statics  one  hundred  and 
fifty  years  old. 

In  1765  a  writer  in  Stahl's  Forstmagazin  discusses  a  proper 
interest  rate  to  use  in  forest  valuation  and  brings  up  the  same  argu- 
ments used  to  this  day  to  show  that  the  ordinary  commercial  rate, 
then  four  per  cent,  was  too  high. 

With  the  rapid  development  of  forest  regulation  and  literature 
about  the  end  of  the  eighteenth  century  came  considerable  discus- 
sion of  forest  valuation,  for  it  now  became  necessary  to  promulgate 
regular  instructions  to  guide  the  practicing  forest  officials.  G.  L. 
Hartig,  Cotta,  Konig  and  Pfeil  all  busied  themselves  with  this 
subject.  Konig  in  1813  first  expressed  clearly  the  value  of  using 
the  net  rental  on  the  land  which  might  be  secured  in  forestry  as 
proper  measure  not  only  of  the  value  of  the  land  but  of  the  success 
of  the  operation  in  silviculture,  protection  and  utilization. 

In  1823  Hundeshagen  first  uses  the  term  forest  statics  and 
defines  it  as  the  ''art  of  measuring  the  productive  forces  and  results 
in  forestry." 

About  the  same  time  Konig  in  his  "Forstmathematik"  discusses 
the  profitableness  of  forestry  and  introduces  the  idea  of  the  profit 
of  undertaking  (unternehmergewinn)  and  that  of  the  per  cent  at 
which  a  given  forest  works.  In  1849  Faustman,  more  or  less  inde- 
pendently, worked  out  the  expectation  or  income  value  of  the  soil, 
first  expressed  by  Konig,  and  gave  to  forest  valuation  this  analysis 
in  a  formula — Se—  which  has  never  been  changed  or  even  modified 
materially  since,  and  which  is  recognized  as  the  most  important 
analysis  in  forest  statics.  He  showed  that  this  analysis  is  applicable 
alike  to  forests  cut  over  at  intervals  (intermittent)  and  to  regulated 
properties  with  yearly  cut. 

In  1858  Pressler  began  publishing  his  works  "Rationelle  Wald- 
wirt"  and  "Waldan  des  hochsten  Ertrags"  which  really  form  the 
beginning  of  a  new  epoch  in  forest  valuation. 

In  1865  Gustav  Heyer  published  the  first  complete  treatise  on 
valuation  and  followed  this  up  in  1871  by  the  first  treatise  on  forest 
statics.  Lehr  worked  over  the  subject  for  the  Handbuch  in  1887, 
and  Kraft,  in  1882,  distinguished  himself  in  his  efforts  to  determine 
correct  methods  of  measuring  the  value-growth  in  the  forest,  in  his 
"Zuwachsrechnungen." 

The  practice,  as  usual,  was  reluctant  to  accept  everything.  Yield 
tables  and  every  kindred  means  of  helping  the  forester  to  know  the 


HISTORY  Otf  VALUATION  9 

volume  and  value  of  the  stand  and  the  growth  in  time  found  no 
difficulty  in  adoption  by  the  practice.  But  when  it  came  to  formulae 
with  compound  interest  and  especially  when  these  formulae  seemed 
to  be  wrong  as  soon  as  five  per  cent,  the  current  interest  rate,  was 
used  and  when  they  seemed  to  lead  to  wholesale  reduction  of  rota- 
tions, the  practicing  forester  ceased  to  have  faith  and  refused  to 
accept. 

Common  sense  and  experience  showed  the  forester  that  it 
required  at  least  eighty  years  (in  a  given  case)  to  grow  marketable 
sizes  of  spruce,  that  smaller  stuff  was  drug  on  the  market.  When 
Pressler's  and  Heyer's  calculations  and  formulae  demanded  a  "finan- 
cial" rotation  of  fifty  years  it  was  clear  to  the  forester  that  some- 
thing was  radically  wrong  and  even  good  men  like  Borggreve,  Urich, 
Bose  and  Baur  denounced  the  whole  method. 

Some  discussion  is  still  going  on,  but  the  truth  is  gradually 
becoming  evident  to  all,  that  all  these  calculations  have  nothing  to 
do  with  the  raising  of  timber,  that  this  is  left  to  silviculture  and 
regulation  as  guided  by  growth  on  one  hand  and  market  on  the 
other,  and  that  these  calculations  merely  try  to  supply  a  correct 
measure,  a  reasonable,  orderly,  acceptable  analysis  to  show  exactly 
what  forestry  is  doing  and  wrhat  it  can  do  in  any  given  case.  If 
then  the  growth  of  timber  is  so  slow  that  the  crop  increases  only 
at  the  rate  of  two  per  cent  compound,  there  is  no  amount  of  calcula- 
tion and  no  juggling  of  methods  and  figures  which  will  change  the 
plain  fact  and  only  one  question  remains — will  we  keep  on  raising 
timber  or  quit?  If  the  timber  is  needed  and  the  land  will  not  grow 
any  other  crops  or  do  better  it  is  quite  certain  that  forestry  will 
continue  regardless  of  the  rate  per  cent  which  it  makes  on  the 
capital. 

At  the  same  time  it  is  becoming  evident  to  all  that  valuation 
is  necessary.  As  pointed  out  before,  the  owner  wants  to  know  what 
is  actually  made,  what  the  land  is  worth  if  used  to  raise  timber, 
whether  expensive  planting  of  transplants  is  actually  better  than 
cheap  natural  reproduction,  etc.  And  he  is  not  willing  to  take  the 
forester's  mere  word  for  it,  he  wants  to  see  by  what  method  of 
calculation  and  upon  what  premises  the  recommendation  is  based. 

In  the  efforts  of  bringing  correct  forest  valuation  and  statics 
into  the  forest  business  the  labors  of  Judeich,  master  of  forest 
regulation,  stand  out  conspicuously.  In  his  long  and  successful 
career  at  the  head  of  the  Saxon  forests,  he  not  only  recommended 
but  introduced  everything  of  value  into  the  practice  and  he  may 
well  be  regarded  as  the  most  powerful  exponent  of  modern  forest 
statics  and  especially  of  the  general  usefulness  of  Se. 


II.    ARITHMETIC  OF  FOREST  VALUATION 

a.     General. 

A  stand  of  timber  fifty  years  old  after  planting  may  be  worth 
two  hundred  dollars  per  acre.  If  this  stand  is  to  remain  and  con- 
tinue to  grow  until  it  is  eighty  years  old,  it  is  right  for  the  owner 
to  ask — at  what  rate  is  the  stand,  now  fifty  years  old,  growing,  what 
per  cent  is  this  growth  on  the  two  hundred  dollars  which  the  stand 
is  now  worth,  etc. 

Since  the  stand  does  not  pay  or  give  up  any  interest,  the  two 
hundred  dollars  or  the  value  of  the  fifty  year  old  stand  is  evidently 
like  a  capital  out  at  interest,  where  the  interest  remains  unpaid,  but 
is  added  to  the  capital  every  year.  In  other  words,  the  stand  of 
timber  grows  like  capital  out  at  compound  interest. 

If  the  owner  wishes  to  know  what  this  stand  has  cost  to  pro- 
duce or  grow  to  the  age  of  fifty  years  he  adds  up  the  various  items, 
cost  of  planting,  care  and  taxes  during  the  fifty  years,  and  the  rent 
on  the  land.  The  ten  dollars  per  acre  spent  in  planting  have  been  out 
for  fifty  years  without  drawing  any  interest,  they  have  grown,  there- 
fore, at  compound  interest  for  fifty  years.  The  expense  of  taxes 
and  care  comes  every  year,  the  sum  paid  out  the  first  year  has  been 
out  for  forty-nine  years,  the  sum  paid  the  second  year  has  been  out 
forty-eight  years,  etc.,  for  none  of  this  interest  has  been  paid. 

If  the  owner  wishes  to  forecast  or  estimate  what  this  stand  is 
worth  to  him  today  if  it  is  to  continue  to  grow  until  it  is  eighty  years 
old,  he  must  first  decide  that  when  eighty  years  old  the  stand  will 
bring,  say,  five  hundred  dollars  per  acre  and  then  discount  the  five 
hundred  dollars  to  the  present  day,  i.  e.,  for  thirty  years. 

From  this  it  is  evident  that  forest  valuation  works  a  good  deal 
with  the  arithmetic  of  interest,  with  discount  and  with  the  summa- 
tion of  series,  usually  geometric  series,  the  geometrical  progressions 
of  many  writers. 

The  following  are  the  more  common  forms  of  interest  here.1 

1The  elementary  treatment  of  these  simple  problems  in  literal  arithmetic 
has  been  fully  justified  by  fifteen  years  experience  in  University  teaching. 
The  student  will  do  well  not  only  to  go  over  this  ground  very  thoroughly, 
work  out  all  formulae  on  paper  and  repeat  often,  but  also  to  speak  aloud 
the  true  meaning  of  each  formula  and  learn  to  state,  as  in  geometry,  exactly 
what  each  formula  means. 


DISCOUNT  AND  PROLONGATION  I  I 

b.  Discount,  Prolongation  and  Rate. 

If  $75  is  put  out  at  4%  compound  interest  for  eight  years,  the 
capital  and  interest  to  be  paid  at  the  end  of  the  period,  the  $75 
capital  grows  as  follows : 

at  the  start,   C0  =  $75;  at  the  end  of 

first  year,       Ct—    75  -f-  interest  for  one  year  =  75  +75  (.04) 

=  75  (i  +.04)=  75  (1.04); 
second  year,  C2  =    75  (1.04)  -f-  interest  =  75  (1.04)  (1.04) 

=  75(1.04')! 

third  year,      C3  =   75  (1.04*)  (1.04)  —75  (i.O43)  ; 
eighth  year,    C8  =  75  (i.O4T)  (1.04)  =75  (l.Qf); 
or,  in  general,  Cn=^C0  (i.opn)  ; 
that  is:  the  final  capital  equals  the  initial  capital  multiplied  by  i.opn. 

Cn 

From  the  above :  -     -  =  C0  or,  the  initial  capital  equals  the  final 
i.opn 

capital  divided  by  i.opn,  or  it  is  equal  to  the  final  capital  discounted 
for  n  years  at  p  per  cent. 

c. 

Also :  —  =  i.opn,  or  i.op"  equals  the  final  capital  divided  by  the 
Co 

initial  capital. 

Since  the  numerical  value  of  i.opn  may  be  found  in  the  table, 
the  value  of  p,  or  the  interest  rate  is  readily  determined. 

C0  (i.opn)  signifies  that  the  initial  capital  C0  is  prolonged  at  p 

Cn 

per  cent  for  n  years.        —  signifies  that  the  final  capital  Cn  is  dis- 
i.opn 

counted  at  p  per  cent,  n  years.2 

c.  Summation  of  Geometrical  Seriez. 

If  the  yearly  expenses  on  a  property  are  $500,  and  these  con- 
tinue for  fifty  years  and  money  is  worth  3%,  what  will  these  ex- 
penses amount  to?  Evidently  the  first  $500  is  out  at  compound 
interest  for  49  years,  the  second  for  48  years,  etc.,  and  it  is  desira- 
ble to  find  a  short  way  of  computing  these  various  amounts. 

2  The  word  capital  is  used  here  in  a  rather  loose  way,  perhaps,  but  not 
more  so  than  .in  ordinary  conversation,  etc.,  and  it  is  a  very  helpful  term  to 
employ  in  these  explanations. 


12  FOKF.ST  VALUATION 

1.  Fundamentally  this  series  is: 

sum,  S  =  a  -j-  ar  -j-  ar2  +  ar3  +  ar4 
and 

Sr  —  ar  +  ar2  -f  ar3  +  ar4  +  ar5 

subtracting  the  upper  from  the  lower, 

Sr— S  — ar5  — a 
or 

S(r-i)=a(r5-i) 
when 

0       a(r5-!) 
:    (r-i) 

since  5  is  the  number  of  terms  in  the  series,  or  n,  and  this  form  is 
perfectly  general,  it  may  be  written : 

a  (rn— i) 

:77^7T 

In  this  series  a  is  the  regular  payment,  and  r  is  the  ratio  between 

ar2 
any  two  consecutive  terms,  as :  ->=-•=  r. 

ar 

2.  Applying  this  to  the  above  case  of  a  yearly  or  current  ex- 
pense of  $500  at  3%. 

sum,  S  =  500  (i-0349)  +  500  (I.0348)  + +500 

S  (1.03)  =  500  (i.035°)  +  500  (i.0349)  -f  etc +  500  (1.03) 

here  1.03  is  the  ratio,  i.  e., 

5oo(i.Q349)  ._ 
500  (I.0348)  ~  r'°3 
subtracting : 

S  (1.03—1)  =5oo(i.o350— i) 

SOP  (I.0350— i) 

(1.03 -i) 

By  looking  up  I.O350  in  the  tables  (see  Appendix),  the  compu- 
tation becomes  perfectly  simple  and  requires  little  time. 

3.  Since  this  same  process  applies  to  any  similar  case  it  may 
be  written  as  a  general  formula : 

a(i.opn—  i) 
1    d.op-i) 

which  may  be  expressed: 

The  sum  of  a  series  of  payments  a  coming  every  year,  contin- 
ued for  n  years  and  compounded  at  p  per  cent. 


PRESENT  VALUE  OF  SERIES  13 

Since  this  sum  represents  the  value  of  all  these  payments  at 
the  end  of  the  period,  it  may  be  termed  the  end  value  of  the  series.3 

500  (i.o350—  i) 

Query  :    Is  the  sum  -  -  the  same  whether  it  begins 

(1.03—1) 

in  1902  or  in  1925,  whether  it  begins  in  ten  years  from  now,  or  has 
run  for  fifteen  years? 

d.     Present  Value  of  the  Series. 

A  farmer  or  forester  may  be  able  to  get  $500  rent  per  year 
from  a  certain  property.  He  may  wish  to  know  the  value  of  twenty 
years  rent  of  this  property  with  a  view  to  raising  money  or  selling 
the  twenty  years'  rent. 

i.  The  end  value  or  sum  of  the  twenty  years'  rent  is  found  as 
above  and  is  expressed  : 

500(1.03"—  i) 

sum  or  end  value  =:  - 
1.03—1 

But  what  is  the  value  of  this  sum  today? 
Keeping  in  mind  that 


-i.opn 
and  that  Cn  is  the  above  sum  or  end  value  of  the  series  : 

CM  500  (l.032°  —  •  i) 

present  value,  Co  =  —  ^  =  /  -  —   N  -  i 
1.03"       (1.03—1)  1.03" 

Expressed  in  words  :  The  present  value  of  a  series  of  payments 
of  $500  coming  every  year,  continued  twenty  years,  compounded 
at  3%  and  discounted  at  the  same  per  cent,  the  first  payment  coming 
a  year  from  now,  in  general, 

a  (i.op"  —  i  ) 

present  value  of  series  =  -,  -  ^r-7  -  ^ 
(i.op—  i)  (i.opn) 

2.  Assuming  that  the  above  series  runs  for  twenty  years  and 
suppose  that  it  has  already  run  for  seven  years,  what  is  its  present 
value  ?  Evidently  the  owner  is  seven  years  to  the  good,  he  does  not 

8  The  student  will  do  well  to  write  these   formulae  exactly  as  he  has 
learned    to    develop    them.      The    temptation    is    to    write,     for    instance, 
a  (i.opn  —  i 

—  .    This  is  correct,  but  it  loses  the  connection,  the  student  for- 
.op 

gets  how  he  came  by  it.  In  solving  ordinary  problems  write  out  the  general 
formula  and  keep  this  before  you.  This  will  avoid  many  mistakes. 


14  FOREST  VALUATION 

need  to  discount  it  for  twenty  years  but  only  for  twenty  less  seven 
or  thirteen,  and  the  case  may  be  written : 

500  (I.0320— i) 
present  value  =  ^— — y—^ 

500  (i.Q320  —  O  i.Q37 
(1.03—1)  i.of 

this  latter  having  the  advantage  that  it  keeps  the  whole  story  clearly 
before  the  student. 

If  in  the  above  case  the  series  does  not  begin  until  fifteen  years 
from  today,  evidently  the  discount  to  present  time  must  be  longer 
by  these  fifteen  years,  and  the  case  may  be  written : 

500  (i.032°—  i) 

present  value  =  — ; rr-p- 

(1.03—1)  I.03**1 
or  to  make  it  more  clear, 

500  (i.Q329  — 1), 


(1.03-1)  (i.o320)  (i.o315) 

e.     Series  of  Periodic  Payments. 

If  a  forest  property  can  be  cut  over  every  fifteen  years  and  at 
•each  return  the  cut  nets  $500  it  may  become  of  interest  to  determine 
what  the  value  of  ten  cuts  of  the  forest  is.  Assuming  that  the 
property  has  just  been  cut  over  so  that  the  next  cut  comes  in  fifteen 
years  and  the  last  cut  in  one  hundred  and  fifty  years,  the  end  value 
or  the  value  of  the  sum  of  these  cuts  is : 

i.     End  value  or  sum  : 

S  =  500  (I.03150-15)  +  500  (i.o3150-30) 500 

S  (i.o315)  =  500  (i.o3150)  +  500  (I.03150-15) 500  (i.o315) 

(Note  that  the  ratio  here  is  I.O315.) 
Subtracting : 

S  (i.o315— i)=5oo(i.o315c— i) 
500  (i.Q3150— i) 
(i.o315-i) 

If  in  the  above  case  we  let  fifteen  years  =  t,  and  10,  the  num- 
ber of  cuts  =  n,  then  150  —  nt,  and  we  may  write  the  general  form  : 

a  (i.opnt  —  i) 
1    d.op4-!) 

Note:  The  student  will  recognize  these  periodic  cases  by  the 
-exponent  t  in  the  denominator. 


INFINITE;  SKRIES  .  15 

Expressed  in  words  :  The  end  value  or  sum  of  a  series  of  pay- 
ments of  $500  each  coming  every  fifteen  years  continued  for  ten 
payments  compounded  at  3%  and  the  first  payment  to  be  made  in 
fifteen  years.  r^c-v^*— 

Query  :  Will  the  above  sum  or  end  value  be  greater  or  smaller 
if  the  first  cut  comes  in  five  years  instead  of  fifteen  years? 

2.  Present  value  of  the  sum  of  a  series  of  periodic  payments. 
The  case  is  the  same  as  under  d  —  I  and  2. 

Present  value  is  : 

a  (i.opDt—  i) 
(i.op*  —  i)  i.opnt 

and  is  modified  according  to  the  time  when  the  series  begins,  or,  in 
the  above  case,  when  the  first  cut  is  made  by  writing  it: 

a  (iopnt  —  i)  ioptj*~- 


(i.op1  —  i)  i.opnt 
where  x  is  the  number  of  years  before  the  first  cut  or  payment. 

.f.     Sum  of  Infinite  Series. 

When  a  farmer  buys  a  farm  he  really  buys  the  yearly  income 
or  rent  of  the  farm  for  all  time,  at  least  there  is  no  set  limit.  In 
practice  about  fifty  years'  rent  is  worth  as  much  as  the  farm,  but 
this  fact  does  not  alter  the  nature  of  the  bargain. 

i.  Using  the  formula  as  developed  under  c  —  2  and  3,  and  tak- 
ing its  present  value  as  under  d  —  i,  present  value: 

a(i.opn—  i) 
(i.op  —  i)  i.opn 

and  letting  n  infinity  or  oo  the  formula  becomes: 

a  (i.op00  —  i) 
present  value  =  (iQp_  j}  ^  „ 

and  since  i.opcc  —  i  -—  i.opc/o  :    present  value 

a  a 


(i.op  —  -i)     i.op00     ~~  i.op—  i  ~~  .op 

If  a  is  the  rental  per  year  or  $500,  and  p  =  5,  then  the  present 

500 
value  of  all  the  rentals  from  this  farm  forever  are  worth  -  or 

•05 

$10,000,  which  simply  means  that  the  farm  is  worth  $10,000  if  it 
brings  a  net  income  of  $500  and  the  buyer  is  willing  to  take  5%  on 


1 6  FOREST  VALUATION 

his  money.     The  $10,000  is  the  income  value  of  the  farm  at  5%, 
and  is  equal  to  the  net  income  capitalized  at  5%. 

2.  If  the  income  is  periodic,  comes  every  fifteen  years,  as  in 
the  case  of  the  forest  cut  over  every  fifteen  years,  the  foregoing  is 
modified  as  follows : 

500  (1.03  °°  15— i) 
present  value  = 


500    (l,03 


i.0315— i     (1.03 
500 


or  in  general : 


(i.op'-i) 


where  A  is  the  periodic  rent  or  money  income  at  each  cut  in  the 
above  case.  If  in  the  above  case  the  first  cut  comes  in  six  years 
instead  of  fifteen  the  owner  is  fifteen  less  six  or  nine  years  to  the 
good  and  this  may  be  expressed  as  follows  :  value  of  property  : 

500    1.03" 
~(i.0315-i) 

That  is,  the  sum  is  prolonged  at  3%  for  nine  years,  or  in  general, 

A    i.op1-* 
-(i.op'-i) 

where  x  is  the  number  of  years  before  the  first  payment  is  due. 
Note:  Care  must  be  taken  to  see  that  the  sum  A  is  really  the 
sum  in  every  case.  To  illustrate  :  A  forest  of  100  acres  can  be  cut 
over  every  20  years  for  $50  worth  of  timber  (stumpage  value)  per 
acre.  The  yearly  expenses  for  the  20  years  sum  up  to  $15  per  acre 
so  that  the  net  income  A  is  50-15  or  $35.  ]f  now  the  first  cut  may 
be  made  at  once  the  value  of  this  property  is  : 

income  value  =  $50  +         M—I,  and  not  '  ^  Q^  __  I 

because  the  first  income  is  larger  by  15  than  the  established  future 
incomes. 


OF  FORMULAE;  17 

g.     Change  of  Periodic  to  Yearly  Payment. 

Where  a  forest  property  furnishes  an  income  only  every  twenty 
years  it  may  be  desirable  to  convert  this  periodic  income  into  a  year- 
ly one.  If  this  property,  on  account  of  the  periodic  income  is  worth, 
or  has  a  safe  income  value  of : 

$48000          48000 

—2-^ =  -g =  $60,000 

1.03   — i      i. 80 — i 

and  the  bank  or  trust  company  is  willing  to  accept  this  as  fact  and 
pay  the  owner  a  yearly  interest  on  the  full  $60,000  at  3%  ;  the  owner 
of  the  forest  would  receive  0.03  X  60,000  =  $1,800  per  year. 
This  may  also  be  stated  as  follows : 

$48,000    _  1800      . 
I.03'-"0  —  i  ~  .03 

or  the  yearly  income, 

_  $48,000  (0.03) 

loOO  —  .YI 

1-03  —  i 
In  general  then : 

A  a  A  (.op) 


(i.op* — i)       (.op)'  i.op* — i 


h.    Table  of  Formulae. 

As  above  developed. 

No.  FORMULA.  MEANING  OF  FORMULA. 

£   _  £  (I0nn)  Prolongation  of  initial  capital  C0  for  n  years  at 

p  per  cent. 

2     ro__     'CQ  Discount  of  final  capital  Cn  for  n  years  at  p 

i.opn  per  cent. 

3.  Cn   _          n  Final  capital  Cn  divided  by  initial  capital  Co  to 
Co  ~                                       find  interest  rate  p. 

ofTon11—  T")       Sum.  or  end  value  of  a  series  of  payments  a 

4.  Cn  =  S  =      (      v ^-      coming  every  year  continued  for  n  years  com- 

(i.op —  i)         pounded  at  p  per  cent. 

Present  value  of  a  series  of  payments  a  com- 
/        n_,>>  ing   every   year   continued    for   n   years    com- 

5.  Co  =  -  —^         pounded  at"  p  per  cent  and  discounted  _at  the 

(i.op — i)  i. op  same  per  cent,  first  payment  to  come  in  one 

year  from  now. 


1 8  FOREST  VALUATION 

a(iopnt j^        Rnd  value  or  sum  of  a  series  of  payments  a 

6.    €n  =  S  =      (    '     t_     '         coming   every   t   years    continued    for   n   pay- 
ments compounded  at  p  per  cent. 

Present  value  of  a  series  of  payments  a  com- 

-     P  _       a(i.opp  — i)  ing  every  t  years  continued   for  n  payments 

(i.pp* — i)  i.oput        compounded  at  p  per  cent,  discounted  at  same 

per  cent,  the  first  payment  to  come  in  t  years. 

The  same  as  No.  7  but  with  the  first  payment 

g      £  —    a^I-°P"  — *)  i-Qpt~x    coming  in  x  years   so  that  the  sum  must  be 
(i.op* — i)  ioprt       prolonged  for  t — x  years.    Where  x  is  greater 
than  t  this  becomes  a  discount. 

Income  value  of  a  property  producing  a  net 

income  a  every  year  computed  by  capitalizing 

a  the   income  a   at  p  per  cent;    or  the  present 

9.     Co—    value  of  a  series  of  payments  a  coming  every 

year  continued   forever  compounded  and  dis-. 
counted   at   p   per   cent,   the   first   payment   to 
come    in    one    year    from    now. 

Present  value  of  a  series  of  payments  A  com- 
ing   every    t    years    continuing    forever    com- 
^  pounded    and   discounted   at   p   per   cent,   the 

10.     Co  —    -, 't first  payment  to  come  in  t  years   from  now. 

This  is  also  the  income  value  of  a  property 
furnishing  a  net  income  A  every  t  years  com- 
puted at  p  per  cent. 

jj      Co  =   — I-°P  "x  Same  as   No.    10  but  with  the   first  payment 

(i.op* — i)  coming  in  x  years  from  now. 

Changing   a   periodic   rental   A   coming   every 

A     (o.op)  t  years  into  a  yearly  rental  a  where  the  value 

i. op1 — i  of  the  property  is  computed  by  capitalizing  the 

income  at  p  per  cent. 


III.    APPLICATION  OF  VALUATION 

A.    TIMBER  CROP,  ITS  NATURE  AND  VALUE. 

Timber  was  not  only  important  to  man  in  the  past,  it  was  a 
necessity,  a  basic  condition  to  every  reasonable  development.  With 
the  great  progress  in  manufacture,  extended  use  of  iron  and  steel, 
especially  with  the  introduction  of  cement  the  importance  of  wood 
seemed  to  decrease  materially  and  it  was  commonly  predicted  that 
wood  had  really  ceased  to  be  a  necessity.  But  the  actual  facts,  the 
consumption  per  head,  the  great  traffic,  export  and  import  of  tim- 
ber, the  intimate  relation  even  dependence  of  many  of  our  industries 
on  a  liberal  use  of  wood  and  the  unexpected  rise  in  price  of  timber, 
the  world  over,  all  flatly  contradict  the  common  assertions  and 
prophecy  of  the  past  years.  (See  Fernow,  Economics.) 

The  people  of  Europe  use  more  wood  today  than  formerly  and 
pay  higher  prices. 

The  timber  import  into  Great  Britain  more  than  doubled  be- 
tween 1850  and  1890  and  is  about  seventy  per  cent  greater  now  than 
in  1890,  having  exceeded  one  hundred  and  twenty  millions. 

Germany,  an  exporter  until  1860,  is  the  second  greatest  timber 
importer  in  the  world  and  this  in  spite  of  intensive  forestry.  France 
is  a  growing  importer  and  is  exceeded  in  its  import  by  Italy. 

In  the  United  States  the  consumption  per  head  has  increased 
from  about  three  hundred  and  fifty  feet  b.  m.  of  lumber  in  1880  to 
over  four  hundred  feet  in  1910,  in  spite  of  the  fact  that  stumpage 
and  lumber  have  increased  in  price  by  about  one  hundred  per  cent. 

Our  railways  have  not  been  able  to  free  themselves  from  the 
wooden  tie,  the  telegraph  and  telephone  lines  use  wooden  poles,  as 
much  lumber  goes  into  ship  building  now  as  previously,  charcoal 
iron  is  still  a  preferred  product,  pulp  and  paper  industries  demand 
more  wood  every  year  and  nearly  every  new  invention,  even  to  the 
propeller  of  the  aeroplane  calls  for  wood. 

In  keeping  with  this  increased  demand  for  wood  prices  have 
advanced  for  a  century.  While  the  price  of  rye,  the  stable  bread- 
stuff, in  Prussia  decreased  by  fifteen  per  cent,  the  price  of  timber 
increased  by  fifty-five  per  cent,  between  1860  and  1903,  and  while 
the  income  from  the  field  remained  nearly  stationary  the  income 
from  forest,  state  forest,  during  the  same  period  increased  by  one 
hundred  and  eighty  per  cent  in  Bavaria,  one  hundred  and  forty- 


20  FOREST  VALUATION 

seven  per  cent  in  Prussia  and  by  over  one  hundred  per  cent  for  all 
Germany. 

Generally  the  demand  is  for  lumber  or  larger  sizes,  and  not 
merely  cordwood  or  quickly  grown  small  stuff.  The  demand  also 
is  more  for  conifers  than  for  hardwoods ;  in  the  United  States  the 
consumption  of  conifers  to  hardwoods  being  about  three  to  one. 

Larger  sizes  require  longer  time  to  grow  so  that  a  forester  of 
central  Europe  does  not  expect  to  cut  his  timber  before  it  is  eighty 
years  old,  the  average  rotations  for  conifers  staying  close  to  one 
hundred  years. 

The  forests  of  the  world  are  limited,  the  really  useful  ones 
amount  to  about  one  acre  for  each  human  being.  In  the  United 
States  we  now  have  about  five  acres  of  woods  per  head  of  popula- 
tion. The  population  increases  and  the  forests  decrease.  Even 
under  present  conditions  the  people  of  the  United  States  are  depend- 
ent for  the  future  on  the  growth  of  five  acres  per  head.  This  growth 
at  present  is  practically  nothing.  Even  if  cared  for,  it  would  prob- 
ably just  suffice  for  the  needs  of  the  population  as  it  is  at  present. 

This  means  that  the  future  will  demand  reduction  in  consump- 
tion regardless  of  all  human  efforts.  With  this  reduction  will  come 
further  advance  in  price.  In  many  localities  this  reduction  has  al- 
ready come,  the  supply  of  raw  material  for  hundreds  of  mills  is 
gone  and  from  the  state  of  Michigan  alone  industries  with  over 
sixty  million  dollars  investment  have  disappeared  in  the  past  twenty 
years.  The  whole  Lake  Region,  New  York,  Pennsylvania,  parts  of 
the  South  and  parts  of  Canada  share  in  this  change.  In  many  local- 
ities over  large  areas  the  change  has  been  from  industrial  prosperity 
to  utter  desolation,  so  that  towns  have  been  deserted,  railway  lines 
taken  up  or  abandoned. 

The  forest  crop  has  its  peculiarities.    Categorically  stated : 

1.  The  forest  takes  many  years  to  grow. 

2.  It  can  use  sand  lands,  cold,  steep,  rocky,  even  poorly  drained 
lands,  and  so  utilize  large  areas  not  useful  otherwise. 

3.  The  forest  improves  the  land,  and  protects  it  against  ero- 
sion. 

4.  It  is  a  much  more  certain  crop  than  the  field  crops. 

5.  It  is  more  independent  of  man,  reproduces  and  grows  very 
well  without  human  effort  wherever  climate,  chiefly  moisture,  is  at 
all  congenial  to  tree  growth. 

6.  It  requires  not  merely  land  but  involves  large  investment 
in  the  growing  stock. 


IMPORTANCE;  OF  TIMBER  21 

A  forester  with  ten  thousand  acres  of  woods  properly  regulated 
so  that  he  can  cut  every  year,  would  cut  about  one  hundred  acres  of 
ripe  timber.  The  other  ninety-nine  hundred  acres  have  timber  from 
one  to  ninety-nine  years  old  and  this  body  of  growing  stock  is  worth 
about  four  or  five  times  as  much  as  the  land  on  which  it  stands. 

In  farming  there  is  very  little  of  this  kind  of  investment,  the 
orchard  trees,  bushes  of  smaller  fruit  and  meadow  grass  resemble  it. 

7.  The  crop  is  not  ripened  in  a  week  or  even  a  year  but  may 
be  cut  when  it  is  thirty,  fifty  or  a  hundred  years  old. 

8.  In  case  of  accident,  fire,  insects,  etc.,  a  large  part  of  the 
damaged  timber  can  be  used,  providing  there  are  means  of  getting 
it  out,  and  a  ready  market. 

9.  Timber  after  it  is  cut  is  not  a  perishable  material  like  po- 
tatoes, fruits,  etc.,  but  is  improved  by  seasoning.    A  body  of  sawed 
timber  may  make  from  three  to  five  per  cent  on  its  value  in  this  way. 
This  gives  independence  in  holding. 

10.  Timber  crop  requires  further  manufacture,  sawmill,  plan- 
ing mill,  pulp,  etc.    It  stimulates  industries. 

11.  The  forest  furnishes  more  material  for  transportation  per 
acre  than  the  farm.    The  latter  about  two  hundred  and  fifty  .pounds 
per  acre,  the  forest  about  one  thousand  pounds. 

12.  The  forest  requires  little  help,  therefore  making  larger 
net  income. 

13.  From  all  ordinary  and  inferior  lands  the  forest  makes  as 
large  a  gross  income  as  does  ordinary  farming  at  present  prices. 

14.  To  the  rural  people  the  forest  is  a  necessity  to  preserve 
sufficient  independence  with  regard  to  fuel  and  building  material. 

15.  The  forest  prevents  erosion,  agriculture  leads  to  erosion. 
The  forest  is  the  only  large  agency  at  the  disposal  of  man  to  influ- 
ence the  flow  of  water  in  streams,  safely,  effectively  and  permanent- 
ly.    In  mountainous  countries  where  the  forest,  because  of  the  to- 
pography, covers  seventy-five  per  cent  of  the  land  it  is  the  greatest 
factor  in  water  distribution. 

16.  Forest  influences  evaporation  and  rainfall,  protects,  locally, 
against  drying  wind.     It  encourages  bird  and  insect  life  and  tends 
to  maintain  a  biological  equilibrium,  helpful  to  man,  especially  in 
agriculture. 

17.  The  forest  is  the  greatest  and  most  important  feature  of 
the  beauty  of  the  earth.    Thinking  man  will  never  wish  to  do  with- 
out the  forest  wherever  it  can  be  made  to  grow. 


22  FOREST  VALUATION 

B.    RISK  IN  FORESTRY. 

The  following  statement  is  made  with  an  apology;  it  is  not 
made  because  there  is  any  special  risk  in  forestry,  or  that  forestry 
is  less  safe  a  business  than  farming  or  other  industries.  It  is  made 
because  there  is  a  very  strong  prejudice  in  the  United  States  and 
because  this  prejudice  is  constantly  being  fostered  and  its  arguments 
repeated  in  legislatures,  among  timber  owners  and  others,  as  an 
excuse  for  not  doing  their  simple  duty  to  the  country  and  the  for- 
ests they  control.  The  people  of  central  Europe  do  not  discuss  the 
risks  in  forestry.  They  have  practiced  forestry  for  more  than  five 
hundred  years.  But  many  of  the  people  of  the  United  States  who 
have  never  practiced  forestry  at  all,  who  still  prefer  to  let  the  native 
forests  burn  up  rather  than  make  any  kind  of  adequate  effort  at 
protection,  are  fully  convinced  that  forestry  is  not  practicable  be- 
cause forest  fires  can  not  be  stopped. 

In  speaking  of  risks,  it  is  usually  the  fire  danger  which  is  in 
the  minds  of  the  people.  As  is  shown  in  detail  in  the  chapter  on 
fire  insurance  in  forestry,  this  danger  is  universally  overrated.  For 
forty  years  the  matter  of  forest  fire  insurance  has  been  agitated' 
abroad,  but  in  spite  of  the  fact  that  some  good  companies  are  ready 
to  take  up  this  insurance  at  $1.80  per  $T,OOO  property,  the  forester 
generally  has  not  felt  the  need  of  insurance  and  at  every  meeting 
where  this  is  discussed  it  is  pointed  out  that  the  actual  losses  from 
fire,  even  in  the  pinery  districts  of  North  Germany  do  not  amount 
to  more  than  one-tenth  the  amount  of  this  premium  so  there  is  no 
reason  why  large  owners  should  spend  their  money  in  this  direction. 
The  statistical  reports  of  Baden  and  Wiirttemberg  do  not  find  it 
necessary  even  to  mention  losses  from  fire,  and  Bavaria  for  years 
staid  below  four  cents  on  the  thousand  dollars  worth  of  woods. 

In  the  United  States  without  any  effort  to  prevent  the  fires  and 
with  many  people  eager  to  get  rid  of  the  forest,  burning  the  forest 
intentionally,  the  losses  from  fire  have  been  very  great.  The  report 
of  the  United  States  Commission  of  Conservation  in  1909  gives  the 
estimated  losses  per  year,  since  1870,  at  about  fifty  million  dollars 
for  saleable  material.  This  is  about  ten  cents  per  acre  per  year  and 
therefore  not  far  from  the  premium  rate  now  demanded  by  the  Ger- 
man insurance  companies,  so  that  it  was  as  cheap  to  let  the  woods 
burn  as  it  would  have  been  to  insure  them  in  up  to  date  companies, 
even  if  this  could  have  been  done.  It  is  evident  then  that  even  in  the 
United  States  in  spite  of  all  neglect,  lack  of  law  and  law  enforce- 
ment, in  spite  of  land  clearing,  etc..  which  made  burning  necessary, 
the  fire  losses  in  the  forest  are  relatively  small.  Had  they  been 


RISK  IN  FORESTRY  23 

spread  over  all  forests  evenly  instead  of  being  concentrated  at  cer- 
tain points,  there  would  not  be  the  general  fear  of  fire  risk  in  for- 
estry. 

As  a  real  menace  to  forestry  insects  and  wood- destroying  fungi 
are  much  more  serious.  Even  in  the  best  cared  for  forests  of  Ger- 
many, fungi,  producing  defects  and  decay  in  the  timber,  and  even 
killing  young  trees,  are  a  constant  trouble.  But  this  is  true  of  the 
wild  woods  as  it  is  of  the  cultivated  forest  and  it  is  true  of  the  farm 
crop  more  than  of  the  woods.  One  of  the  greatest  tasks  of  the 
United  States  Department  of  Agriculture  and  of  all  state  experi- 
ment stations  is  to  find  remedies  for  the  many  plant  enemies  of  our 
crops  and  fruits.  Millions  are  spent  every  year  by  the  farmer  in 
spraying,  etc.,  and  millions  more  are  lost  for  lack  of  effective  treat- 
ment. The  same  is  true  with  insects;  scale,  louse,  moth,  weevil, 
chinch  bug,  wheat  fly,  and  potato  beetle  have,  and  do  cost  many 
millions  every  year.  If  the  fly  gets  into  wheat,  the  chinch  bug  into 
the  corn  or  the  boll  weevil  into  cotton  the  loss  is  often  complete.  An 
attack  of  insects  in  timber,  even  if  severe  enough  to  kill,  is  only  a 
partial  loss,  all  large  stuff  can  be  used,  wherever  forestry  has  become 
a  real  business  with  means  of  utilization  and  a  market.  While  the 
German  forester  is  much  more  concerned  about  insects  and  fungi 
than  about  forest  fires,  it  does  not  occur  to  anyone  to  think  of  these 
difficulties  as  a  risk  sufficient  to  discourage  forestry  as  a  business. 
Weber  in  the  Handb-uch  and  Endres  in  his  Forst  Politik  made  no 
effort  to  estimate  these  losses.  Like  those  from  fire  in  the  United 
States  they  are  great  both  here  and  abroad  but  they  even  up  as  they 
do  in  farming.  To  the  small  owner  they  are  serious,  in  large  hold- 
ings they  form  a  regular  trouble  to  figure  with.  Endres  (p.  95) 
mentions  the  losses  from  wind,  snow,  ice  and  insects,  (leaves  out 
fire)  and  says  that  in  all  computation  of  averages  these  losses  are 
inconspicuous — "Kommen  nur  wenig  zum  Ausdruck.'' 

As  regards  the  growth  and  reproduction  of  the  crop  itself  which 
expresses  more  properly  the  certainty  or  success  in  crop  production, 
the  forest  far  excels  the  farm  crop.  From  Michigan  to  the  Gulf, 
the  forest  was  practically  unbroken,  there  were  no  large  "burns" 
or  other  gaps.  Nature  had  reproduced  one  crop  after  another,  the 
crops  had  grown  to  old  age,  died  and  given  way  to  new  crops. 
Windstorms,  insects  and  fungi  had  collected  their  toll  but  the  forest 
was  there  and  asked  no  help.  In  the  most  intensive  forestry  in  Ger- 
many less  than  twenty  per  cent  of  the  expenses  are  devoted  to  plant- 
ing, etc.,  to  protection  and  care  of  the  crop,  about  fifty  per  cent  is 
spent  in  harvesting.  Where  the  forest  has  not  been  abused  and 
where  the  climate  is  good  the  new  crop  comes  in  without  any  help 


24  FOREST  VALUATION 

or  delay,  and  even  where  planting  is  justified  by  better  returns,  this 
planting  makes  rarely  more  than  ten  per  cent  of  the  total  expenses 
on  a  forestry  property.  The  growth  of  the  forest  is  quite  secure,  a 
dry  season  may  produce  less  wood,  but  the  next  season  makes  up 
for  it  and  the  harvest  of  the  year  does  not  show  the  effects  at  all. 
Frost,  hail,  extremes  of  cold  and  heat,  etc.,  all  affect  the  forest,  but 
only  in  a  small  degree  and  the  cut  of  the  year  remains  unchanged. 
Insects  may  partly  defoliate  a  stand  of  oak  and  hurt  it  quite  severe- 
ly ;  but  if  the  stand  recovers,  as  is  usually  the  case,  the  man  who  har- 
vests this  stand  will  never  know  the  difference  and  the  effects  of  the 
injury  are  hardly  felt  or  known  by  the  business. 

In  farming  the  time  of  ripening  is  a  critical  period ;  a  few  days 
of  dry  weather,  dry  hot  winds,  a  hail  storm,  rain,  etc.,  may  largely 
destroy  the  season's  yield.  Nothing  of  this  kind  exists  in  forestry. 
If  a  sixty-year-old  stand  is  not  growing  well,  if  fungi  have  started 
their  work  and  the  stand  begins  to  be  defective  it  is  cut  and  used 
and  another  put  in  its  place. 

In  a  twenty-year  average  farming  over  large  areas  must  be 
content  with  about  sixty  per  cent  full  or  normal  crop,  even  in  the 
great  staples,  wheat,  corn,  etc.,  while  forestry,  where  properly  prac- 
ticed at  all,  produces  over  seventy  per  cent  of  a  full  crop.  In  fruit 
farming  it  is  doubtful  if  the  average  crop  is  twenty  per  cent  of  a 
regular  full  crop. 

From  this  sketch  it  is  evident  that  the  risk  in  forestry  is  small, 
smaller  than  in  farming  and  much  smaller  than  in  most  city  business. 
It  is  this  very  security  which  has  distinguished  the  state  forests  and 
forests  of  other  large  owners  and  which  has  made  the  forest  the 
valuable  and  desirable  property  it  is.  Where  the  forest  is  neglected, 
stocked  with  poor  species  and  handled  by  poor  methods,  coppice  in 
France,  for  instance,  and  where  mismanagement  has  left  unmade 
suitable  improvements,  it  is  only  natural  that  the  value  of  the  prop- 
erty is  small,  in  keeping  with  low  income.  But  even  in  these  cases 
it  is  not  risk  but  low  income,  due  to  neglect,  which  is  the  fault. 


C.    THE  INTEREST  RATE  IN  FORESTRY. 

a.    General. 

When  a  farmer  who  paid  $6,000  for  a  loo-acre  farm  finds  that 
for  10  years  back  he  averaged  $300  net  income  per  year  for  his  crops 
he  naturally  asks — what  per  cent  is  this  on  my  investment?  If  he  is 
satisfied  with  the  5%  which  it  made  he  will  be  satisfied  with  farm 


INTEREST  RATE  25 

business,  if  he  feels  that  he  ought  to  make  10%  on  his  money  he 
will  want  to  sell  out. 

In  this  case  it  is  a  matter  of  experience  and  fact,  with  $300  in- 
come 5%  is  what  the  farm  made  on  $6,000  cost  price.  If  now  a  man 
wishes  to  buy  this  farm  and  is  shown  that  the  farm  made  $300  net 
income  per  year  he  may  say :  the  farm  is  good  for  $300  per  year, 
is  a  safe  property,  I  may  as  well  put  my  money  into  this  farm  as 
keep  it  in  the  bank  at  three  per  cent.  To  him  the  income  value  of  the 

$300 

farm  is:  -     -  or  $10,000  and  he  may  be.  satisfied  to  pay  this  price. 
0.03 

To  another  man  who  values  his  money  at  6%  the  farm  is  worth 
only  half  this  amount.  In  this  case  the  three  per  cent  or  six  per  cent 
are  set  by  the  man  who  wishes  to  buy  the  farm  and  judges  its  value 
by  the  income  it  makes  and  a  per  cent  which  he  determines  himself. 

In  forestry,  too,  these  two  fundamental  cases  of  determining 
interest  rate  occur  and  very  commonly  are  both  present  in  the  same 
calculation. 

If  a  planted  stand  of  pine  sixty  years  old  is  ready  to  cut  and 
worth  $300  per  acre  the  owner  may  want  to  know  what  per  cent 
was  made  on  the  investment.  He  knows  that  it  cost  $10  to  plant, 
that  the  land  cost  $20  per  acre  and  that  it  cost  60  cents  per  acre  each 
year  to  take  care  of  the  forest  and  pay  taxes.  The  ten  dollars  for 
planting  have  been  out  at  compound  interest  for  fifty-nine  years, 
and  the  question  arises — at  what  per  cent?  Evidently  it  is  for  the 
man  to  choose  this  per  cent.  When  the  calculation  is  finished  and 
he  finds  that  all  expenses  for  the  sixty  years  amount  to  $180  per 
acre  he  can  find  the  net  income  and  real  value  of  his  business. 

The  calculation  of  what  interest  rate  a  stand  of  timber  actually 
makes  or  has  made  is  comparatively  simple  and  there  is  little  dis- 
agreement as  to  method.  But  what  per  cent  to  assume  or  set  in 
calculations  of  forest  valuation  is  quite  a  different  question,  and  the 
opinions  often  differ  and  have  differed  since  valuation  began. 

To  choose  a  high  rate,  such  as  the  current  rate  of  interest  paid 
by  business  men  and  farmers  gives  the  calculation  a  business-like 
air  and  seems  practical.  But  even  the  reasonable  rate  of  five  per  cent 
will  seem  to  prove  most  forestry  a  failure  or  lead  to  a  demand  for 
absurdly  low  rotations,  etc.  To  choose  a  low  rate,  say  two  or  three 
per  cent,  is  unpopular,  seems  to  discredit  forestry,  sounds  theoretic 
and  unpractical. 

But  the  choice  must  be  made,  forest  valuation  is  impossible 
without  it.  The  man  who  puts  money  into  land  and  timber  for  for- 


26  FOREST  VALUATION 

estry  must  have  some  reasonable  calculation  to  show  what  he  ex- 
pects of  the  business.  Tax  commissions  and  legislatures  will  not 
change  their  methods  unless  shown  convincing  facts  as  argument. 
It  is  self-evident  that  the  assumed  interest  rate  and  all  calculations 
based  on  this  rate  have  nothing  at  all  to  do  with  the  growth  of  the 
timber  and  all  these  calculations  can  possibly  do  is  to  give  a  reason- 
able measure  of  what  actually  takes  place  and  compare  forestry  as 
a  business  with  other  kinds  of  business.  The  question  is — is  there 
a  reasonable  and  acceptable  basis  for  interest  rate  to  set  in  forestry? 

b.    Interest  rates  paid  and  made. 

In  the  United  States  today  the  ordinary  loan  pays  about  5%, 
timberland  owners  and  many  industrials  pay  6%  and  over,  the  far- 
mer pays  about  6  %  in  the  east  and  north,  larger  per  cents  in  the 
south  and  west,  so  that  it  was  reported  in  1912  that  the  farmer  of 
the  United  States  borrows  about  6,000  million  dollars  at  an  average 
rate  of  8%.  Large  railroad  companies,  etc.,  pay  four  or  five  per 
cent.  Cities  and  states  pay  about  four  per  cent  on  their  bonds,  the 
United  States  Government  can  borrow  at  from  two  to  two  and  a 
half  per  cent,  and  the  savings  banks  with  their  enormous  deposits  - 
pay  generally  three  per  cent,  while  millions  of  dollars  are  deposited 
in  banks  and  draw  no  interest. 

In  Germany  mortgages  pay  about  four  or  four  and  a  half  per 
cent,  bonds  about  3.4%  to  3.8%. 

Interest  rates  are  higher  in  new  and  undeveloped  countries,  the 
West  pays  higher  than  the  East. 

In  the  fourteenth  century  the  common  rate  in  Germany  was  ten 
per  cent,  it  sank  to  five  per  cent  by  the  sixteenth  century.  After 
the  Napoleonic  wars  it  went  up  to  eight  per  cent,  then  it  sank  to 
three  per  cent  by  1870,  rose  again  to  five  and  then  declined  to  present 
rates. 

2.  The  fact  that  a  man  pays  six  per  cent  on  his  mortgage  is 
no  indication  that  the  man  makes  six  per  cent  in  his  business,  what- 
ever that  may  be.  This  seems  self-evident,  and  yet  it  is  the  most 
common  fallacy  in  connection  with  this  discussion  to  assume  that 
because  a  certain  per  cent  is  paid  by  the  men  of  a  certain  industry 
when  in  need  of  money  this  rate  is  also  made  or  approximated  by 
the  industry. 

a.  Since  agriculture  in  the  broad  sense  really  includes  forest- 
ry, it  is  fair  to  use  farm  business  as  a  criterion  and  see  what  farm 
business  pays.  The  data  for  the  following  analysis  are  taken  from 
circular  I32-A,  1913,  of  the  United  States  Department  of  Agricul- 
ture, and  based  on  the  Census  of  1910. 


INTEREST  ON   FARM  27 

The  average  farm  of  the  United  States  has  138  acres  and  is 
valued  at  $6,443,  including  stock  and  implements. 

The  total  or  gross  income  is  $980,  leaving  off  cents,  of  which 
$860  is  the  value  of  the  crop,  including  stuff  fed. 

In  the  summary  on  page  four  of  circular  132,  the  data  are  ar- 
ranged as  follows : 

"Total  gross  income .$980 

Total  expenses 340 

Net  farm  income 640 

Interest  on  investment  5% 322 

Labor  income,  including  unpaid  family  labor  and  all 
the  farm  furnishes  toward  the  family  living  except 
milk  and  cream.  Does  not  include  income  from 
outside  sources,  and  the  amount  paid  for  live  stock 

bought  must  be  deducted  from  this  sum" 318 

"Interest  on  mortgage,  $1,715  at  6% $102 

Available  for  live  stock  and  for  family  living $537" 

These  same  data  may  be  arranged  as  follows,  where  it  is  as- 
sumed that  the  farmer  and  his  family  should  receive  for  their  labor 
at  least  the  wages  of  one-  farm  laborer  without  board,  since  they 
board  themselves,  and  that  it  takes  $50  per  year  to  replace  teams 
and  other  live  stock. 

Gross  income  per  year $980 

Expenses : 

Labor    $102 

Fertilizer 18 

Feed 47 

To  maintain  buildings   49 

To  maintain  implements   39 

Taxes,  at  0.6%   38 

Miscellaneous .' 44 

Salary  of  farmer  and  family 360 

Replacement  of  live  stock 50     $750 


Net  income   . $230 

This  $230  is  three  and  a  half  per  cent  on  the  $6,443  capital. 
If  the  $102  interest  on  the  mortgage  is  deducted  there  remains  only 
two  per  cent  interest  actually  made  by  the  average  farm  of  the 
United  States  in  1910. 


28  FOREST  VALUATION 

Since  the  average  farmer  with  his  family  can  not  be  engaged 
at  less  than  $500  per  year  and  usually  demand  part  or  all  the  gro- 
ceries for  the  household  paid  by  the  employer  it  is  evident  that  the 
above  three  and  a  half  per  cent  is  too  high  and  it  is  doubtful  if  two 
per  cent  is  actually  made. 

This  fully  agrees  with  the  findings  of  Cornell  Agricultural  Col- 
lege and  with  bulletin  41,  United  States  Department  of  Agriculture, 
1914,  which  shows  that  the  interest  made  on  selected  farms  in  Indi- 
ana, Illinois  and  Iowa  in  1911  was  about  three  and  a  half  per  cent 
and  in  cash  rent  system  less  than  three  per  cent.  It  is  evident  that 
many  farmers  make  no  interest  at  all  and  do  not  even  make  the  com- 
mon farm  hand  wages. 

Whether  this  fact  is  explained  by  saying  that  farm  products 
are  sold  too  cheaply  or  that  cost  of  production  is  too  high  is  imma- 
terial, the  fact  remains  that  the  rate  actually  made  by  the  most  im- 
portant industry  of  the  country  and  the  industry  most  closely  re- 
lated to  forestry  is  less  than  three  per  cent.  In  Germany  farming 
paid  about  two  per  cent,  in  some  provinces  only  one  and  a  half,  in 
1899. 

b.  What  other  kinds  of  business  actually  make  is  little  known 
and  much  disguised.    If  the  losses  and  gains  of  our  stores,  factories, 
railways,  etc.,  could  be  known,  and  if  the  natural  wealth,  timber, 
coal,  etc.,  could  be  deducted  and  also  the  entrepreneur's  risk  and 
effort,  if  these  could  be  ascertained,  it  is  doubtful  if  the  business  of 
the  country  really  makes  one  and  a  half  per  cent,  even  in  good  times 
like  1900-1910. 

Generally  it  is  a  fact  that  the  current  rate  paid  by  the  farmer 
is  not  made  by  the  farm,  it  is  equally  certain  that  as  an  average  it 
is  not  made  by  other  business.  To  employ  or  set  the  current  rate  as 
measure,  then,  would  discourage  most  of  our  ordinary  industries. 

c.  What  rates  a  good  forest  business  makes  is  well  illustrated 
by  the  state  forests  of  Saxony  where  the  rate  actually  made  has  been 
2.3  to  2.6%  for  over  forty  years.    Since  a  great  deal  of  forest  prop- 
erty is  assessed  on  a  basis  of  income  and  an  assumed  rate  of  inter- 
est this  interest  rate  in  Germany  frequently  is  an  argument  in  circle. 

d.  Germany  today  uses  an  interest  rate  of  3%  or  less,  in  Baden 
2^,  in  all  calculations  of  values  of  land,  timber  or  forest. 

e.  In  adopting  an  interest  rate  in  forest  valuation  we  have  the 
choice  and  say : 

I.  Adopt  a  rate  which  the  ordinary  forest  business  can  make, 
which  encourages  the  improvements  and  methods  necessary  for  a 
secure  paying  enterprise.  The  best  measure  and  basis  is  the  farm 
business. 


VALUATION  OF  LAND  29 

2.  Adopt  a  rate  which  the  business  can  not  make,  which  tends 
to  abandonment  of  land  and  great  loss,  which  even  under  good  con- 
ditions discourages  all  improvements  and  all  better  but  more  ex- 
pensive methods. 

Germany,  Switzerland  and  Denmark  have,  unconsciously  chosen 
the  first,  France  and  England  the  second,  England  has  no  forests, 
France  little  and  mostly  poor  forests.  See  also  Professor  Kirkland's 
article  on  the  influence  of  the  interest  rate  on  timber  production. 
Washington  University  Forestry  Club  Annual,  1915. 


D.     VALUATION  OF  LAND  OR  SOIL. 

Generally,  land  is  valuable  in  proportion  as  it  produces  rent. 
A  city  lot  is  valuable  owing  to  its  location,  a  field  or  forest  land  is 
valuable  owing  to  the  crop  it  can  produce.  The  value  of  the  crop  is 
the  measure  of  the  value  of  the  land.  But  even  in  the  simplest  case 
the  matter  is  more  or  less  complicated.  The  value  of  the  crop  does 
not  depend  only  on  the  kind  and  amount  of  the  crop,  but  also  on  the 
market  and  transportation  and  so  on  the  location  of  field  or  forest. 

Again  the  same  field  may  be  used  to  raise  wheat,  corn,  hay  or 
timber  and  for  each  crop  the  same  field  may  have  a  very  different 
value.  In  farming,  nature  demands  a  change  of  crop  and  it  is  im- 
possible or  at  least  unprofitable  to  raise  wheat  on  the  same  area 
continuously.  Generally  the  crop  making  the  largest  income  is  most 
trying  to  the  land  and  succeeds  only  on  good  land  and  at  reasonable 
intervals.  Some  crops,  like  tobacco,  are  very  exhausting,  while  oth- 
ers like  clover  and  timber  tend  to  improve  the  land. 

a.     Cost  value,  sale — and  income — or  expectation — value. 

1.  If  a  man  bought  a  tract  of  land  ten  years  ago  for  five  thou- 
sand dollars  and  if  the  income  from  this  land  has  paid  expenses  and 
interest  it  is  evident  that  this  tract  today  costs  him  the  original  five 
thousand.     Generally  however,  the  case  is  complicated,  the  income 
has  been  irregular,  greater  or  less  than  expenses  and  interest,  and 
so  the  cost  value  of  a  piece  of  land  is  not  as  clear  or  easily  com- 
puted as  it  would  seem. 

2.  The  sale  or  market  value  of  land  seems  to  require  no  ex- 
planation.    It  is  determined  by  sales  actually  made  in  the  district, 
by  supply  and  demand.     It  is  interesting  to  see  what  conditions  are 
most  important  in  determining  this  sale  value.    The  conditions  may 
be  divided  as  follows : 


30  FOREST  VALUATION 

a.  Conditions  affecting  the  Income: 

1.  Conditions  which  are  part  of  the  property  itself;  area  and 
shape  of  the  property,  soil,  topography,  water  supplies  and  drain- 
age, improvements. 

2.  Conditions  which  are  not  part  of  the  property,  or  which 
extend  beyond  the  property :  climate,  market,  facilities  for  trans- 
portation, labor,  taxation,  character  and  business  of  the  surround- 
ing people,  and  demand  for  properties. 

b.  Conditions  not  affecting  the  income  but  important  from  the 
standpoint  of  sentiment : 

Beauty  of  the  property  and  surroundings,  social  conditions, 
church,  school,  etc.,  family  ties,  habits,  love  of  sport,  "land  hunger," 
etc. 

With  farmlands  it  is  often  more  the  second  group  of  conditions, 
(b)  which  set  the  price,  so  that  generally,  the  world  over,  farm  lands 
are  rated  and  paid  for  at  a  price  higher  than  is  warranted  by  income. 
But  even  in  forestry  it  is  frequently  this  second  set  of  conditions 
which  are  decisive  so  that  the  majority  of  large  estates  held  as  for- 
est parks  today  in  the  United  States  are  held  more  for  love  of 
scenery  or  sport  than  as  properties  for  income. 

The  sale  value  fluctuates  greatly  with  demand  for  land  and  is 
easily  affected  by  "booms."  It  is  an  old  experience  in  the  United 
States  to  see  a  few  land  dealers,  by  means  of  shrewd  advertising, 
succeed  in  a  few  sales  at  high  prices.  Whether  always  bona  fide  or 
not,  such  sales  tend  to  raise  the  price  of  land  for  the  entire  district, 
in  spite  of  the  fact  that  there  is  no  justification  for  this  advance  in 
larger  crops  or  better  prices. 

2.  The  income  value  of  the  land,  or  expectation  value  de- 
pends on  the  crop,  rent  or  income  which  the  land  produces  and  the 
interest  rate  which  is  assumed  or  is  set  by  the  individual  making  the 
valuation.  As  indicated  before : 

net  income 

=  income  value, 


o.op 

wrhere  p  is  the  interest  rate  assumed  and  where  the  income  is  a 
yearly  one  as  in  farming. 

The  income  itself  depends  on  the  conditions  enumerated  under 
sale  value  and  the  ability  of  the  owner. 

The  interest  rate  usuall  varies  with: 

a.     Outside  conditions : 

Money  market,  location  of  property  (old  country  as  against 
newly  settled  districts),  good  and  bad  times,  etc. 


COST- VALUE;  OF  LAND  31 

b.     Conditions  of  property  and  business  itself: 
Size  of   property,  term  of   investment,   regularity   of   income, 
safety  of  property  and  income. 

b.    Cost-value  and  sale-value  of  land  or  soil  in  forest 
properties  in  the  United  States. 

Aside  from  the  sales  of  small  woodlots,  etc.,  it  is  generally 
true  that  the  land  itself  is  not  considered  in  sales  of  timber.  In  the 
past  and  even  at  the  present  time  it  is  the  common  practice  in  buy- 
ing and  selling  timberlands  to  estimate  the  merchantable  timber  or 
the  stuff  now  ready  for  ax  and  market  and  to  set  a  price  only  on 
this  marketable  material  leaving  out  of  consideration  both  the  land 
and  the  growing  stock  smaller  than  merchantable.  In  many  cases 
even  part  of  the  large  timber  is  considered  non-merchantable  and 
is  not  paid  for.  For  instance,  balsam,  cedar  and  oak  in  California, 
hemlock  and  balsam  in  the  northwest,  Douglas  fir  and  balsam  in  the 
northern  Rockies,  hardwoods  in  the  northeast,  gum  and  other  .hard- 
woods in  the  south. 

Generally,  then,  the  cost  value  and  the  sale  value  of  forest  lands 
in  the  real  forest  districts  of  the  United  States  is  practically  nothing. 
In  the  Great  Lakes  Region  millions  of  acres  were  simply  abandoned 
by  the  lumbermen  after  the  timber  had  been  cut  and  allowed  to  re- 
vert for  non-payment  of  taxes.  Of  late  these  lands  are  turned  over 
to  some  land  company,  often  the  same  men,  to  sell  to  settlers.  In 
the  south  millions  of  acres  of  cutover  lands  can  be  bought  at  less 
than  three  dollars  per  acre  though  there  is  a  remnant  of  tree  growth 
usually  worth  the  price  paid  for  the  land.  Michigan  and  Wisconsin 
and  Ontario  have  sold  millions  of  acres  in  the  last  twenty  years  at 
prices  generally  not  over  one  dollar  per  acre  and  in  these  cases,  too, 
the  land  was  bought  more  for  the  remnants  of  timber  than  the"  land 
itself. 

New  York  bought  over  one  and  one-half  million  acres  of  land, 
over  seventy-five  per  cent  covered  with  timber,  at  about  three  dol- 
lars and  sixty  cents ;  Pennsylvania  bought  about  a  million  acres  at 
two  dollars  and  twenty-seven  cents ;  Pisgah  forest  of  eighty  thous- 
and acres  was  bought  in  1914  at  five  dollars  for  land  and  timber 
and  over  thirty  thousand  acres  in  the  White  Mountains  were  bought 
at  about  four  and  a  half  dollars  an  acre,  though  in  both  cases  nu- 
merous old  abandoned  farms  were  included,  and  the  remaining  tim- 
ber is  worth  the  price  paid.  In  1915  a  tract  of  over  thirty-six  thous- 
and acres  in  North  Carolina  was  bought  at  one  dollar  and  ninety 
cents  an  acre  for  land  and  timber. 


32  FOREST  VALUATION 

c.    INCOME  VALUE  OF  LAND  OR  SOIL  IN  FORESTRY. 

Expectation  value  of  soil  or  Se. 

When  a  man  buys  land  to  raise  timber  and  does  this  as  a  matter 
of  business  and  not  merely  sentiment,  for  sport  or  summer  home, 
etc.,  the  case  is  one  of  investment  and  he  values  the  land  in  propor- 
tion as  it  produces  an  income  or  crop.  In  business  the  income,  here 
net  income,  which  can  be  made  from  the  land  by  raising  a  particu- 
lar crop,  timber,  is  the  only  reliable  measure  of  value. 

To  the  man  who  is  in  the  business  of  raising  the  crop,  whether 
farm  crop  or  timber,  this  net  income  per  acre  is  not  only  the  correct 
measure  of  the  value  of  the  land  but  it  is  also  a  measure  of  the  work 
or  operation  of  raising  the  crop.  A  good  farmer  or  forester  who 
selects  the  right  kinds  of  crop,  best  suited  to  the  soil  and  climate, 
cares  for  the  land,  sows,  tends  and  harvests  well,  gets  a  larger  net 
income  than  a  less  competent  man.  Any  mistake  or  neglect  reduces 
the  income  and  with  this  the  income  value  of  the  soil  or  land. 

In  this  way  the  income  value  of  the  land  becomes  a  measure  of 
the  value  of  land  and  the  effectiveness  of  its  management. 

i.     General  method  of  calculation  for  Se. 

In  the  case  of  farm  property  where  the  income  from  each  acre 
is  a  yearly  one,  the  income  value  of  a  given  acre  of  land  is  the  net 
income  capitalized.  If  an  acre  of  land  on  a  ten-year  average  can 
produce  $10  net  income  and  money  is  rated  at  3%  the  income  value 

10 

of  this  acre  of  land  is or  $33^3^ 

0.03 

Where  an  acre  of  land  is  planted  to  pine  and  the  pine  requires 
eighty  years  to  grow  to  acceptable  size,  the  income  from  this  acre 
comes  not  yearly  but  every  eighty  years-  It  is  a  periodic  income  or 
rental  which  is  assumed  as  in  the  case  of  a  farm  to  come  forever. 

The  present  value  of  these  net  incomes,  coming  every  eighty 
years  is  the  value,  of  the  acre  of  land.  If  the  timber  is  worth  $400 
and  it  has  cost  $175  to  raise  it;  the  net  income  is  $225  and  the  pres- 
ent value  of  all  these  net  incomes,  coming  every  eighty  years, 

Se  =  (i. op1— i)   ==  (i.o3S(t—  i)  =  (10.64—1)  = 

which  means  that  this  particular  acre  of  land  is  worth  $23.40  when 
used  to  raise  pine  where  this  is  allowed  to  grow  to  the  age  of  eighty 


INCOME-VAIAJE)  OF  I.AND  33 

years,  where  the  expenses  are  $175  during  the  eighty  years,  and 
where  the  final  crop  is  worth  $400  and  money  is  rated  at  3%.  That 
the  value  of  this  acre  may  change  if  a  different  kind  of  timber  is 
raised  or  if  the  pine  is  cut  at  sixty  years,  or  expenses  are  lower  or 
higher,  or  if  a  different  rate  of  interest  is  set,  is  evident.  It  is  clear 
too,  that  if  the  man  pays  $23.40  per  acre  for  this  land  and  uses  it 
as  outlined  above,  he  makes  three  per  cent  on  his  investment  and 
no  more.  This  Se  then,  is  rather  the  maximum  price  which  he  can 
actually  pay. 

It  is  evident,  also,  that  these  same  considerations  hold  in  case 
of  a  piece  of  farmland.  The  same  acre  of  land  produces  a  larger 
income  with  sugar  beets  or  potatoes  than  with  wheat  and  more  with 
wheat  than  hay,  so  that  the  same  acre  has  different  income  value  in 
different  years  owing  to  change  in  crops,  yield,  expenses,  etc.  Yet 
this  income  value  is  considered  the  safest  measure  of  value  and 
forms  the  basis  of  all  farm  valuation  and  assessment. 

2.     The  usual  case  of  Se. 

a.  Premises : 

Area,  40  acres ;  method,  clear  cut.  and  plant. 

Rotation  r,  80  years ;  interest  rate  p,  3%. 

Cost  of  planting  c,  $6  per  acre. 

Yearly  expenses,  taxes  and  care,  e,  twenty-five  cents  per  acre. 

Yield  of  timber  eighty  years  old,  or  Yr,  30  M  ft.  at  $10,  $300 
per  acre. 

Thinning  when  stand  is  20  years  old,  T20,  just  pays  expenses, 
hence  no  income. 

Thinning  when  stand  is  40  years  old,  T4o,  yields  5  cords  at  $3 
or  $15  per  acre. 

Thinning  when  stand  is  60  years  old,  T60,  yields  10  cords  at 
$4.50  or  $45  per  acre. 

b.  Gross  'income  per  acre  at  end  .of  rotation : 

Final  yield  or  cut  80  years  old,  Yr $300 

Thinning  when  20  years  old,  Tzo o 

Thinning  when  40  years  old,  T4O, 
$15,  with  interest  for  80-40  years 

or  $15(1. 0340)     50.40 

Thinning  when  60  years  old,  T6o, 

$45  with  interest  for  80-60  years 

or  $45(1.03")    81 


Total    $43140 


34  FOREST  VALUATION 

c.     Total  expenses  per  acre  at  end  of  rotation. 

Cost  of  planting,  c,  $6  with  interest 

for  eighty  years  or  6  (i.O3s<))  ......  $  63.84 

Care,  protection,  and  taxes,  e,  0.25, 
coming  every  year  with  interest. 


Total  expense  ..................  $144.09 

d.     The  net  income  per  acre  at  end  of  rotation: 

$431.40 
144.09 


$287.31  per  acre. 

This  net  income  of  $287.31  per  acre  may  be  and  is  expected  to 
come  every  80  or  r  years  and  the  value  of  all  these  net  incomes  or 
the  value  of  the  acre  of  land  producing  them  is  : 

value  of  land  per  acre,  Se         2*7-3i  —  =  $2980 

(i.o;f—  i) 

value  of  40  acres  :  $1,192. 

In  the  above  simple  case  it  is  assumed  that  the  plantation  suc- 
ceeds and  that  it  does  not  require  any  filling  in  or  cultivation,  etc. 
If  such  work  has  to  be  done  it  is  charged  exactly  like  the  plantation 
itself.  Similarly,  if  there  are  more  thinnings  as  there  would  be 
where  intensive  work  is  justified  and  also  where  there  are  other  in- 
comes, such  as  grazing,  turpentine,  etc.,  these  incomes  are  credited 
and  prolonged  exactly  like  the  thinnings  in  the  above  simple  case. 

It  is  evident  from  the  above  that  this  analysis  is  clear  and  logi- 
cal that  it  resembles  computations  made  in  other  lines  of  business, 
requires  only  ordinary  interest  arithmetic  and  that  there  is  no  neces- 
sity for  putting  it  into  a  formula  which  often  seems  to  hinder  rather 
than  help. 

Nevertheless  it  is  convenient  and  makes  the  matter  much  clearer 
and  easier  to  discuss,  and  to  understand  the  relation  and  influence 
of  the  various  factors  if  it  is  arranged  in  a  concise  formula,  and  the 
usual  arrangement  follows  closely  the  above  sample  case  : 

e.     Formula  of  Se  : 


f  Tc(.I.OPr-c)_c(l.Opr)— 


-  ... 

be  =  _  .  _  (lop  —  i  ) 

(i.opp—  i) 

where  Yr  is  the  stumpage  value  of  one  acre  of  timber  r  years  old  : 


FORMULA   FOR   SD  35 

Ta  the  stumpage  value  of  the  thinnings   from  one  acre  a 

years  old,  etc.  ; 

c     the  cost  of  planting,  or  otherwise  reproducing,  one  acre.  ; 
e     the  regular  yearly  expenses  of  tax  and  care  for  one  acre 

of  land; 
r     the  rotation  ; 
p     the  interest  rate  employed  or  assumed; 

Se  the  expectation  or  income  value  of  one  acre  of  land  or 
soil.* 

(i.opr—  i) 
In  the  above  formula  the  term^  -  -  may  also  be  writ- 

(i.op—  i) 

e  e 

ten  -  -  (  i  .opr  —  i  )  —  E  (  i  .opr  —  i  )   where  E  =  —        =  e 

(i.op—  i)  .op 

capitalized  so  that  E  is  a  sum  of  money  which  will  bear  a  yearly  in- 
terest e  at  p  per  cent  and  therefore,  if  put  out  at  interest  will  ''take 
care"  of  the  regular  yearly  expenses  e. 

The  formula  then  may  also  be  written  : 

Yr4-Ta(i.opr-a))  +  ......  etc.  —  cd.opr)—  E(i.opr—  i) 


which  may  be  and  usually  is  simplified  into  : 

Yr  +  Ta(i.opr-")-f  ......  etc.  —  c(iopr) 

(i.op'-i) 


*  It  is  of  great  help  to  the  student  to  use  these  terms  or  symbols  con- 
sistently and  use  no  more  terms  than  are  actually  necessary.  To  use  Y  and 
Yr  interchangeably  or  use  Yr  for  one  acre  and  for  a  given  area  of  many  acres. 
etc..  soon  confuses  even  able  students.  Where  new  cases  come  up,  especially 
cases  which  are  not  really  standard,  but  exceptional,  it  is  much  better  to  write 
out  fully  what  each  part  means  and  use  the  full  analysis,  as  in  the  above 
sample  case,  rather  than  try  to  force  it  into  a  formula. 
*  This  fprmula  is  written  by  Emdres  as  follows  : 


which  means  exactly  the  same  but  changes  the  order  for  c  so  that  it  confuses 
the  beginner  and  the  general  student.  As  stated  before,  the  average  student 
will  ftfrd  it  helpful  to  stay  closely  with  the  simple  forms  and  write  them  out 
in  full  so  that  the  formula  shows  clearly  just  how  it  was  derived. 


36  FOREST  VALUATION 

E.    VALUE  OF  SOIL  AND  STATICS. 

Just  as  in  farming,  so  in  forestry,  the  net  income  is  larger  on 
good  land  and  with  good  management  than  on  poor  land  or  with 
less  efficient  work.  vSince  the  income  value  of  the  land  is  the  net 
income  capitalized  at  an  arbitrary,  accepted  per  cent  this  income 
value  serves  as  a  measure  of  land  and  management.  With  the  ex- 
penses constant,  or  what  may  be  assumed  the  same,  with  the  same 
kind  and  quality  of  management,  the  income  and  with  this  the  in- 
come value  increases  only  with  the  quality  of  the  soil ;  the  better  the 
land  the  greater  its  income  value.  Similarly,  on  the  same  acre  of 
land  the  income  and  with  this  the  income  value  of  the  land  increases 
with  the  efficiency  or  quality  and  correctness  of  the  work  and  man- 
agement. 

It  is  interesting  to  see  how  the  income  value  of  the  soil  differs 
with  change  in  the  various  factors,  what  these  several  factors  de- 
pend upon,  and  how  they  vary  under  ordinary  conditions. 

a.     Relation  of  Se  and  its  Factors. 

1.  Increase  of  the  final  cut,   Yr,   increases  the  income  and 
therefore  the  value  of  the  land.     Since  Yr  is  the  value  of  one  acre 
of  timber  r  years  old  it  is  evident  that  everything  which  increases 
this  Yr,  such  as  good  planting,  right  thinning,  good  prices,  cheap 
logging,  etc.  also  increases  the  net  income  and  income  value. 

2.  Thinnings  not  only  increase  the  total  income  but  as  they 
come  long  before  the  final  cut  can  be  made,  twenty  to  sixty  years  in 
ordinary  cases,  they  help  to  bear  expenses  which  are  piling  up  at 
compound  interest. 

A  good  thinning  practice  raises  the  quality  of  the  final  cut  and 
so  increases  Yr;  a  very  severe  thinning  practice  may  cut  down  the 
Yr  in  volume  and  if  too  early  also  in  quality. 

3.  Cheap  planting  or  small  c  means  small  expenses,  for  every 
dollar  spent,  even  at  three  per  cent,  becomes  nineteen  dollars  in  a 
hundred  year  rotation.     But  if  cheap  planting  means  poor  planting 
it  may  lead  to  a  poor  stand,  reduce  the  income  from  thinnings  and 
cut  down  the  final  cut  or  Yr.    A  large  c,  therefore  may  mean  larger 
income.     From  the  formula  it  is  clear  that  whenever  c  (i.opr)   is 
larger  than  Yr  +  Ta  (i.opr'a),  etc.,  the  term  becomes  negative,  a 
condition  which  applies  to  practically  all  young  stands. 

4.  The  current  yearly  expenses  for  taxes,  protection,  etc.,  ac- 
cumulate with  compound  interest  and  reduce  the  income.    They  are 


FACTORS  OF  SE  37 

generally  small  in  forestry  and  their  importance  in  the  business  is 
easily  overrated. 

Where  cheap  protection  means  unreliable  protection,  the  kind 
that  fails  in  danger  season,  the  saving  in  current  expenses  is  the 
proverbial  penny  wisdom.  As  appears  from  the  formula,  the  capital- 
ized expenses  E  affect  the  income  or  the  income  value  of  the  soil 
uniformly;  they  are  constant  regardless  of  rotation  and  so  do  not 
cause  the  maximum  of  income  value  to  come  either  earlier  or  later. 

A  glance  at  the  formula  shows  that  whenever  E  is  greater  than 

Ta(i.opr-a)  etc.—  c(i.opr) 


(i.opr—  i) 

the  business  is  carried  on  at  a  loss  and  the  income  value  of  the  soil 
becomes  negative. 

5.  The  rotation,  r,  affects  the  value  of  the  crop  and  in  this 
way  the  net  income  and  income  value.    In  spruce,  pine,  maple,  etc., 
a  five  or  ten  year  rotation  would  mean  a  final  cut  of  mere  brush  of 
practically  no  value.     Even  a  twenty  year  rotation  would  in  most 
cases  not  even  pay  for  the  plantation.     For  these  short  rotations 
then,  Se  is  negative  regardless  of  quality  of  land  or  management. 
In  the  above  cases  the  business  would  just  about  pay  expenses  at  a 
thirty  year  rotation  ;  the  income  value  would  continue  to  increase  and 
reach  a  maximum  at  about  eighty  years.    After  that  the  expenses, 
planting  and  current  expenses,  together  with  the  discount  would 
grow  faster  than  the  timber  and  Se  would  decrease,  in  spite  of  the 
fact  that  the  final  cut  would  be  larger  at  one  hundred  years  than 
at  eighty  years. 

The  following  figures  for  spruce  site  III  (Endres,  p.  275)  illus- 
trate this  :   At  three  per  cent  Se  is  : 

Age,  or  rotation  years        30    40    50    60    70    80    go    100     no    120 
Income  value  of  land 
per  acre,  Se  .....  $        —14     13    38    53    59    59    56      51      46      41 

which  shows  that  even  in  the  German  forest  and  at  three  per  cent 
a  rotation  of  thirty  years  leads  to  loss  and  negative  value  of  Se  of 
$14  per  acre  ;  that  Se  increases  with  increase  in  rotation  up  to  sev- 
enty years,  declines  after  eighty  years  and  reaches  a  value  of  $41 
with  a  1  20  year  rotation. 

6.  The  interest  rate,  p,  which  is  assumed  in  these  calculations 
greatly  affects  the  results.    If  in  the  sample  case  outlined  above  the 


3§  FOREST  VALUATION 

interest  rate  of  five  per  cent  is  set  instead  of  three,  the  Se  of  $29.80 
changes  to  a  negative  quantity ;  i.  e.,  the  same  land  and  management 
which  gives  to  the  land  an  income  value  of  $29.80  per  acre  becomes 
a  losing  business  to  the  man  who  values  his  money  at  five  per  cent. 
The  same  is  illustrated  by  the  following  figures  for  spruce,  site  II 
(Endres,  p.  274).  The  income  value  of  the  land,  Se,  with  an  80 
year  rotation  is  at 

3  % $105  per  acre 

2l/2% 173  per  acre 

2  % 285  per  acre 

b.  Values  of  the  Factors  of  Se,  and  Variation  in  these  Fac- 
tors under  different  conditions. 

i.  The  final  cut,  Yr,  depends  on  the  growth  to  produce  the 
crop  and  on  market  to  pay  for  it. 

a.  Both  site  and  species  affect  the  final  cut.  These  possible 
variations  are  laid  down  in  the  yield  tables  for  different  species  at 
least  so  far  as  volume  and  size  or  quality  are  concerned.  In  the 
more  modern  tables  and  for  the  settled  conditions  of  the  Old  World 
they  are  commonly  worked  out  for  money  values  or  made  into  mon- 
ey yield  tables.  The  yield  tables  giving  size  and  volume  of  timber 
per  acre  have  been  a  matter  of  experience  and  growth.  Even  for 
the  different  districts  of  central.  Europe  they  are  being  improved 
continually  and  will  be  modified  further  with  better  methods  of  sil- 
viculture, added  experience  and  more  accurate  and  extended  statis- 
tics. Nevertheless,  for  central  Europe  they  are  good  now,  quite  the 
best  we  have ;  they  are  more  reliable  than  farm  yield  tables  and  far 
surpass  in  safety  the  forecasting  of  ordinary  business  enterprises. 
In  all  new  forest  districts  including  the  United  States,  data  for  yield 
tables  are  gradually  accumulating.  Asa  beginning  the  practice  takes 
what  it  finds  in  the  wild  woods  and  the  assumption  is  that  what 
nature  has  produced  unaided  will  be  produced  again  on  the  same 
land  and  by  the  same  species.  Since  the  wild. woods  generally  do 
not  produce  as  much  timber  nor  as  good  a  quality,  for  ordinary 
rotations,  the  figures  of  yield  and  growth  are  conservative.  This 
is  doubly  true  of  money  yield  tables.  In  fact  money  yield  tables  for 
most  parts  of  the  United  States  where  they  are  based  on  present 
stumpage  prices  are  conservative  to  the  point  of  uselessness,  as  is 
clearly  shown  by  comparing  present  stumpage  prices  with  those  of 
twenty-five  years  ago. 


VARIATION    IN   YR 


39 


b.  The  influence  of  site  or  quality  of  land,  including  climate, 
etc.,  is  very  great.  Endres,  (p.  94)  using  Lorey,  Weise  and  Baur's 
tables  gives  the  following  figures  for  the  one  hundred-year-old  stand 
of  timber  fullv  stocked : 


Yield  per  acre. 

Relative  figures  or  per  cent  for  different  sites. 

On  site  I 
Cubic  feet. 

I 

II 

III 

IV 

V 

Pine  

9200 

100 

78 

61 

48 

38 

Spruce 

16000 

100 

81 

64 

49 

35 

White  fir  ... 

17200 

100 

Si 

64 

49 

— 

Beech    

.  10400 

100 

84 

65 

49 

33 

Since  this  classification  itself  is  really  based  on  arbitrary  but 
generally  accepted  figures  for  the  volume  of  timber  per  acre  at  a 
given  age  it  may  be  said  that  the  above  figures  are  an  argument  in 
a  circle.  But  the  important  fact  is  that  in  actual  practice  the  forester 
deals  with  lands  on  which  the  yield  at  one  hundred  years  differs  as 
above.  The  figures  clearly  show  therefore,  the  great  influence  of 
the  site  on  the  same  kind  of  timber.  That  the  influence  of  site  is 
just  as  great  in  the  United  States  as  in  central  Europe  is  certain; 
the  western  yellow  pine  in  the  Black  Hills  makes  a  two  or  three  log 
tree  and  yields  about  five  or  ten  thousand  feet  per  acre,  while  in 
parts  of  California  and  Oregon  it  is  a  six  to  eight  log  tree  yielding 
forty  thousand  feet  and  over. 

The  influence  of  site  on  the  money  value  of  the  final  cut,  the 
Yr  of  the  calculation,  is  even  greater  than  on  the  volume,  since  the 
quality  and  price  are  largely  matters  of  size  and  good  land  produces 
larger  timber  in  the  same  time.  Schwappach  in  his  tables  of  1902 
gives  the  following  for  spruce,  one  hundred  years  old :  Volume  of 
site  I  per  acre  is  13800  cubic  feet,  its  value  $2,085  ;  putting  the  val- 
ues for  site  I  equal  to  100,  the  relative  figures  for  the  different  sites 
are: 

Sites I  II  III         IV 

Volume    100  "85  65  50 

Value  per  acre 100  75  54  36 


so  that  site  IV  produces  half  as  much  timber  in  volume,  but  only  a 
little  over  one-third  in  value.     In  pine  the  average  price  per  100 


4°  FOREST  VALUATION 

cubic  feet  of  timber  in  the  stand  120  years  old,  in  Prussia  is  given 
by  Schwappach  (pine,  1908,  p.  144)  as  follows: 

Site  I    $12.00  per  100  cubic  feet 

Site  II    1 1.20 per  100  cubic  feet 

Site  III    9.10  per  100  cubic  feet 

'Site  IV    8.25  per  TOO  cubic  feet 

Site  V    6.60  per  100  cubic  feet 

These  figures  well  illustrate  the  effect  of  site  on  size,  quality,  and 
price  of  the  material. 

The  final  cut  in  practice  and  for  large  areas  involving  a  variety 
of  sites  is  best  illustrated  by  the  cut  in  the  German  state  forests. 
According  to  Endres'  Forst  Politik,  p.  96,  in  the  year  1900  the  cut 
for  the  state  forests  was  set  as  follows :  cubic  feet  of  stuff  three 
inches  and  over,  per  acre  of  forest  area : 

Baden    73  cubic  feet 

Wiittemberg    71  cubic  feet 

Saxony    70  cubic  feet 

Bavaria    60  cubic  feet 

Prussia    43  cubic  feet 

Which  means  about  sixty  or  sixty-five  per  cent  of  what  the 
yield  table  calls  for,  on  a  basis  of  site  III  and  the  usual  rotations. 
Since  this  condition  is  rapidly  changing  owing  to  the  conservative 
cutting  in  the  past,  the  later  figures  for  Wurttemberg  are  interest- 
ing. 

In  the  three  years  1906-1908,  the  cut  of  the  state  forests  aver- 
aged one  hundred  and  three  cubic  feet  per  acre  of  woods.  Of  this 
about  one-third  is  hardwoods,  mostly  beech.  Using  beech  with  one 
hundred  and  twenty  year  rotation  and  spruce  with  ninety  year  rota- 
tion, and  assuming  on  an  average  forty  per  cent  of  area  site  II,  and 
sixty  per  cent  site  III  (very  nearly  the  actual  condition  as  reported 
by  Graner)  the  cut  according  to  Schwappach's  tables  should  be  one 
hundred  and  forty  cubic  feet  to  be  full  or  normal.  Being  one  hun- 
dred and  three  cubic  feet  it  is  seventy-three  per  cent  of  normal,  or 
in  other  words,  the  practice  today  in  Wurttemberg  is  seventy- 
three  per  cent  efficient,  or  successful.  Since  the  cut  is  increasing 
in  all  states  it  is  clear  why  the  state  forest  authorities  of  Bavaria  in 
their  late  instructions  consider  seventy-five  or  eighty  per  cent  a  pos- 
sible goal. 


VARIATION  IN  YR  41 

c.  The  value  of  the  final  cut,  Yr  is  greater  for  spruce  than  for 
pine,  greater  for  pine  than  beech,  etc.     The  following  German  fig- 
ures for  site  II,  age  one  hundred  years,  ilnstrate  this : 

Spruce    $1563  per  acre 

Pine    627  per  acre 

Oak     377  per  acre 

Beech 347  per  acre 

While  this  comparison  is  not  quite  fair,  since  oak  does  not  really 
develop  quality  until  after  one  hundred  years,  yet  it  bears  out  the 
general  experience  that  the  hardwoods  do  not  make  the  values  like 
conifers,  and  that  tolerant  conifers  produce  more  value  per  acre  than 
intolerants.  When  it  is  remembered  that  the  land  producing  pine  is 
generally  poor  sand,  while  oak  land  is  good  loam  or  clay,  commonly 
fair  agricultural  land,  the  above  comparison  is  even  more  impressive. 

d.  The  final  cut  depends  on  the  methods  of  silviculture.     A 
slow,  long  drawn  out,  natural  restocking  of  the  land  wastes  time 
and  can  not  possibly  produce  the  same  volume  and  value  of  Yr  which 
a  good  prompt  reproduction  does.    Defective  or  imperfect  cover  at 
time  of   reproduction  wastes  space  and  leads  to  irregular  stands 
where  some  trees  have  too  much,  others  too  little  room  and  light. 
Very  dense  natural  reproduction  leads  to  dense  stands,  great  com- 
petition, and  if  no  thinning     is  practicable,  leads  to  great  loss  of 
material  by  death  and  decay,  loss  of  growth,  and,  besides  producing 
less  healthy  and  safe  conditions,  it  leads  to  smaller  timber,  small 
volume  and  value  of  Yr. 

A  good  planting  practice  assures  prompt  reproduction,  proper 
spacing,  healthy  growth,  safe  conditions,  and  with  these,  larger  and 
better  timber  and  larger  Yr.  A  saving  of  five  years  in  the  rotation 
or  what  amounts  to  the  same,  a  Yr  five  years  better  in  size,  volume 
and  value  may  be  secured  by  good  planting. 

Mixed  stands  have  often  been  claimed  to  produce  a  larger  cut 
per  acre.  The  proof  has  never  been  furnished ;  the  practice  abroad 
does  not  believe  it,  the  pure  stand  is  gaining  and  not  losing  ground. 
Mayr  was  right  in  pointing  out  the  poorer  development  of  crown 
and  waste  of  space  on  the  line  of  contact  between  different  species 
such  as  beech  and  spruce,  etc. 

Clear  cutting  methods  save  in  logging  and  so  increase  Yr.  On 
good  ground  with  proper  improvements,  roads,  etc.,  the  skidding 
is  saved  and  buyers  haul  directly  from  the  area.  In  parts  of  Ger- 
many this  item  alone  offsets  the  cost  of  planting.  Methods  like  the 
coppice  produce  small,  cheap  stuff,  often  difficult  to  market.  The 


42  FOREST  VALUATION 

general  experience  of  France  with  its  non-paying  coppice  woods 
on  relatively  valuable  sites  clearly  proves  this. 

The  regular  timber  forest  with  rotations  over  sixty  years  alone 
makes  a  satisfactory  Yr. 

e.  Up  to  reasonable  limits  the  final  cut  varies  almost  directly 
with  the  length  of  the  rotation.     German  experience  indicates  that 
for  pine,  spruce,  fir  and  beech  a  one  hundred  and  forty  year  rotation 
produces  as  high  a  Yr  as  is  likely  to  be  produced  by  any.  higher  rota- 
tion.    The   difficulty  of  keeping  the   stand  intact  and  growing  is 
very  great  and  generally  demands  the  cut  before  one  hundred  and 
forty. 

While  the  effects  of  the  methods  of  treatment,  silviculture,  on 
Yr  are  quite  well  understood  and  fully  recognized,  their  estimate  in 
dollars  and  cents  is  not  easy.  This  is  especially  true  of  the  effects 
of  thinning,  and  it  is  one  of  the  important  tasks  of  the  forest  ex- 
periment stations  today,  to  gather  reliable  data  based  on  careful  ex- 
periment. Schwappach  has  made  an  effort  to  estimate  the  effects 
of  thinnings  in  beech  and  spruce,  and  to  a  less  extent  in  pine,  but 
these  efforts  are  still  tentative.  That  a  full  and  clear  appreciation 
of  these  facts  really  constitutes  the  most  important  part  of  a  for- 
ester's judgment  regarding  his  business,  is  self-evident. 

f .  The  market  with  its  prices  and  grading  determines  the  value 
of  the  crop  when  once  it  is  produced.     In  the  United  States  the 
market  is  irregular,  uncertain  and  localized ;  it  is  excellent  in  New 
York,  Boston,  Chicago,  etc.,  but  poor  in  the  forest  districts.     Most 
of  the  timber  has  to  be  transported  over  long  distances  and  the  price 
at  the  mill  and  in  the  forest  is  low  as  a  result.     Cypress  goes  from 
the  Gulf  to  the  northern  states  and  east ;  red  fir,  sugar  pine  and  red- 
wood are  railroaded  clear  across  the  continent. 

A  good  telephone  pole  or  a  1,000  feet  of  good  pine  retail  for 
as  much  money  in  the  towns  of  southern  Michigan,  Ohio  or  Indiana 
as  they  do  in  Germany.  But  an  enormous  supply  of  merchantable 
or  mature  stuff  ready  for  the  ax  encourages  destructive  competi- 
tion among  manufacturers  so  that  while  good  quality  pine  is  retailed 
in  Michigan  as  high  as  one  hundred  dollars  per  thousand  feet  it  may 
be  sold  by  the  manufacturer  in  California  or  Oregon  for  less  than 
cost  of  production,  leaving  no  Yr  at  all  for  the  stand  in  the  forest. 

These  conditions  are  rapidly  changing  and  the  value  of  the  stand 
in  the  United  States  as  in  Germany  will  be  determined  largely  by 
the  cost  of  growing  the  timber. 

As  it  is,  the  stumpage  price  or  unit  price  of  Yr  has  increased 
rapidly  being  now  more  than  one  hundred  per  cent  greater  than 
twenty-five  years  ago. 


STUM  PAGE;  IN  EUROPE 


43 


In  Europe  timber  prices  have  increased  for  one  hundred  years 
past,  they  have  practically  doubled  between  1830  and  1890,  but  have 
remained  rather  constant  since  that  time. 

The  following  figures  from  Endre's  Forst  Politik,  p.  120,  will 
illustrate  changes  in  price  of  timber  sold  from  state  forests  in  Ger- 
many. 

Average  price  in  dollars  per  100  cubic  feet  solid,  paid  in  the 
state  forests  .of: 


Average 
for  the  • 
years 

Prussia 
All  wood 
$  per  100  c.  ft. 

Bavaria 
All  wood 
$  per  loo  c.  ft. 

Baden 
All  wood 
$per  looc.  ft 

Saxony 
Only  wood 
3"  and  over 
$  per  loo  c.  ft. 

1830-39 

2.50 

.... 

.... 

4.60 

1840-49 

3.00 

.... 

.... 

5-70 

1850-59 

3.20 

3-50 

4.10 

6.40 

1860-69 

3-80 

4.10 

6.50 

7-90 

1870-79 

4.40 

5.20 

7.90 

9.20 

1880-89 

4.40 

5-oo 

6.40 

9.30 

1890-99 

4.90 

5.8o 

7.60 

10.  2O 

1900 

6  .  fio 

7.00 

8.70 

11.80 

These  prices  were  paid  for  the  timber  cut  or  cut  and  piled,  in 
part  at  least,  skidded  to  the  road,  i.  e.,  in  the  form  in  which  the  tim- 
ber is  usually  sold  by  the  authorities.  Log  timber  is  usually  sold  full 
length,  cordwood  is  piled  in  the  usual  way. 

Prices  for  pine  in  eastern  Prussia  in  sound  clean  sticks  contain- 
ing thirty-five  cubic  feet  or  more  according  to  Schwappach,  1908, 
p.  143,  are  $13  to  $1540  per  TOO  cubic  feet  solid,  or  about  $16  to  $19 
per  thousand  feet  b.m.  actual  stumpage.  For  spruce,  Schwappach 
gives  the  folowtng  prices: 

Logs  class  I    $20.40  per  M.  feet  bm.  stumpage 

Logs  class  IT    19.20  per  M.  feet  bm.  stumpage 

Logs  class  III iS.Soper  Mk  feet  bm.  stumpage 

For  oak  in  Prussian  state  forests  the  same  author  gives  prices 
as  follow  for  logs  cut  and  skidded : 

Logs  over        24  inch  diameter  $42  per  100  cubic  feet  or  $53  per  M.  feet  bm. 
Logs  20-24  inch  diameter    35  per  100  cubic  feet  or    44  per  M.  feet  bm. 

Logs  16-20  inch  diameter    28  per  100  cubic  feet  or    35  per  M.  feet  bm. 

Logs  12-16  inch  diameter     17  per  100  cubic  feet  or    22  per  M.  feet  bm. 

For  beech  saw  timber  Schwappach  uses  the  average  price  of  $7 
per  100  cubic  feet  or  $8.90  per  M  feet  stumpage  for  north  Germany 


44 


FOREST  VALUATION 


and  $2.10  to  $4.90  per  100  cubic  feet  solid  for  cordwood  and  small 
timber,  also  on  the  stump. 

Average  prices  for  log  timber  cut  and  usually  peeled  and 
skidded,  i.  e.,  ready  to  haul  from  the  woods,  in  the  state  forests  of 
Wurttemberg  were  as  follows : 


Oak 

Conifers 

$per  100  c.ft. 

$  per  M.  ft.  bm. 

$  per  100  c.ft. 

$  per  M.  ft.  bm. 

1880-84 
1885-89 
1890-94 
1895-99 

17.70 
17.40 
24.00 
24.60 

22.25 
23.00 
30.00 
30.75 

9.00 
9.50 
10.50 

12.80 

11.50 
ii.6o 
13.20 
16.00 

g.  The  cost  of  exploitation  and  transportation  are  intimately 
associated  with  market  and  greatly  affect  the  value  of  the  final  cut. 
In  the  United  States  the  cost  of  getting  the  timber  cut,  skidded  and 
hauled  to  the  railway,  landing,  etc.,  has  not  changed  very  much  in 
spite  of  the  great  variety  of  conditions  under  which  the  work  must 
be  done.  A  cost  of  from  four  to  six  dollars  per  M  feet  of  logs 
would  probably  include  seventy-five  per  cent  of  all  operations.  Nor 
has  this  cost  changed  materially  in  the  last  twenty  years.  Generally 
the  employment  of  machinery  and  the  utter  disregard  for  the  safe- 
ty and  condition  of  the  forest  have  enabled  forest  utilization  to  keep 
down  the  expenses  of  logging  or  immediate  exploitation. 

Timber  exploitation  in  Europe  works  with  cheaper  labor,  less 
equipment  and  less  efficiency.  In  districts  with  good  and  ample 
road  systems  it  is  cheaper  than  the  work  in  the  United  States,  in  all 
difficult  situations  and  whenever  it  works  over  long  distances  as  is 
the  rule  in  the  United  States,  it  is  not  cheaper  and  often  eats  up  the 
larger  part  of  the  value  of  the  cut. 

The  cost  of  exploitation,  (Werbung's  Kosten),  for  all  timber 
in  the  state  forests  was  as  follows  in  1900: 

Prussia    $0.98  per  100  cubic  feet,  or  about  $1.25  per  M.  feet  bm. 

Saxony    1.26  per  100  cubic  feet,  or  about     1.55  per  M.  <feet  bm. 

Wurttemberg    1.33  per  100  cubic  feet,  or  about     1.65  per  M.  feet  bm. 

But  these  figures  are  not  readily  comparable  to  logging  costs 
in  the  United  States.  The  stuff  includes  cordwood,  poles,  ties,  mine- 
props,  etc.  Moreover  the  material  is  commonly  not  skidded,  and 
even  if  skidded,  it  is  so  only  for  a  very  short  distance,  generally  less 
than  two  hundred  yards. 


TRANSPORTATION  AND  YR  45 

The  logging  costs  in  the  German  states  have  increased  in  keep- 
ing with  better  wages ;  this  increase  is  over  fifty  per  cent  since  1870 
and  the  increase  continues.  Usually  the  costs  vary  but  little  from 
year  to  year  and  so  may  be  estimated  very  closely.  Transportation 
of  logs  to  mill  and  of  timber  and  .lumber  to  markets  affects  Yr  very 
seriously  everywhere.  In  the  United  States  the  transportation  of 
logs  to  mill  formerly  meant  long  drives,  costly  improvements,  much 
loss  by  "sinkers"  and  a  great  deal  of  risk.  Today  it  involves  costly 
railway  construction  where  the  one  cut  must  pay  for  all  improve- 
ment in  this  way  subtracting  heavily  from  the  value  of  the  standing 
material. 

Transportation  to  market  in  the  United  States  is  normally  long 
distance  haul.  The  average  haul  in  the  United  States  for  cypress 
and  southern  pine  may  be  assumed  to  be  over  six  hundred  miles  be- 
tween mill  and  customer ;  for  western  timber  over  fifteen  hundred 
miles,  and  even  for  Lake  states'  stuff  over  three  hundred  miles,  and 
this  practically  all  by  rail. 

In  Europe  too  the  influence  of  transportation  costs  on  the  price 
of  timber  is  evident  in  spite  of  shorter  railway  haul  and  more  exten- 
sive use  of  waterways.  The  same  kind  of  timber  in  east  Prussia 
and  Poland  sells  for  fifty  to  one  hundred  per  cent  less  than  it  does 
in  the  industrial  Rhine  districts. 

The  influence  of  a  good  system  of  roads  is  well  illustrated  in  the 
Black  Forest,  while  the  utter  lack  of  roads  in  parts  of  the  Alps  pre- 
vents many  villages  from  having  any  material  income  from  the  for- 
est properties. 

h.  The  volume,  quality  and  value  of  the  final  cut  depends  on 
the  care  and  protection  of  the  stand  and  the  presence  or  absence  of 
injurious  agencies  like  storm,  fire,  insects,  fungi,  drought,  snow, 
sleet,  etc. 

On  every  large  property  some  of  these  enemies  are  at  work  at 
different  times  and  it  is  the  rare  exception  that  a  stand  of  timber 
passes  through  its  entire  life  of  one  hundred  years  or  more  without 
suffering  more,  or  less  injury.  Fungi  and  insects  are  always  present 
and  need  only  suitable  conditions  to  multiply  into  regular  epidemics. 
Often  these  enemies  are  assisted  through  the  mistakes  of  the  for- 
ester in  selecting  the  wrong  species  for  the  site  in  question,  by  keep- 
ing too  dense  a  stand,  etc.  It  is  due  to  these  enemies  and  injurious 
conditions  that  most  stands  of  timber,  especially  intolerants,  "break," 
or  open  up  long  before  the  end  of  the  rotation  and  often  compel 
earlier  cutting  or  underplanting,  and  on  poor  sites,  adoption  of 
shorter  rotation. 


46 


FORKST  VALUATION 


Much  of  the  trouble,  particularly  from  fire,  can  be  averted  by 
proper  protection  and  much  can  be  done  by  prompt  and  frequent 
thinning  and  underplanting  of  older  stands  on  poor,  sandy  sites. 
For  this  reason  a  saving  in  current  expenses  or  in  caring  for  the 
stand  may  prove  false  economy  by  reducing  the  final  cut. 

2.  Thinnings.  The  incomes  from  thinnings  are  set  down  in 
most  modern  yield  tables  for  the  important  species  and  the  several 
sites  and  have  of  late  been  expressed  as  money  tables.  These  tables 
for  thinnings  are  not  as  fully  developed  as  the  tables  for  the  final 
yield  because  of  the  great  difference  in  the  practice  of  thinnings. 
Different  practicing  foresters  still  disagree  within  rather  wide  limits 
in  their  views  regarding  the  proper  degree  of  thinning.  In  addi- 
tion the  market,  income,  labor,  etc.,  may  enable  one  forester  to  thin 
early  and  often  and  compel  another  to  postpone  thinnings,  and  to 
come  only  at  long  intervals.  Modern  practice  in  good  intensive 
work  expects  a  thinning  every  ten  years  and  in  young  stands  of  oak 
on  good  sites  five  years  is  considered  a  long  interval. 

Like  the  final  cut,  Yr,  the  thinnings  vary  in  volume  and  value 
income  with  species,  site  and  practice. 

a.  For  a  stand  one  hundred  years  old,  on  site  I,  as  per  Schwap- 
pach,  the  sum  of  all  thinnings  taken  out  during  the  life  of  the  stand 
and  the  volume  and  value  of  the  main  stand  one  hundred  years  old 
are  as  follows  for  wood  of  all  sizes  per  acre : 


Main  stand  100  years  old 

Thinnings  taken  out 
during  life  of  stand 

Volume  cu.  ft. 

$  per  acre 

Volume  cu.  ft. 

$per  acre 

Pine  
Spruce  .  .  . 
Oak  

6550 
11500 
6150 
9200 

627 
2028 
798 
43i 

6100 
10800 
7800 

5720 

363 
450 
535 
193 

Beech  ... 

Arranging  these  values  of  thinnings  as  per  cents  of  the  volume 
and  value  of  the  final  cut  gives  the  following  interesting  compari- 


son 


Thinnings  expressed  as  per  cent  of  main  stand  or  final 
cut  of  stand  one  hundred  years  old,  site  I 
In  volume 


Oak    126% 

Pine    94% 

Spruce    94% 

Beech    62% 


In  value 
67% 

57% 

22% 

45% 


VALUE;  OF  THINNINGS 


47 


In  oak  and  pine  thinning  out  of  a  large,  volume  is  necessary,  in 
spruce  and  beech  it  is  not  necessary  but  it  is  possible  and  desirable. 
The  smaler  value  of  thinnings  is  due  to  inferior  quality,  is  most 
conspicuous  in  spruce  and  least  in  beech  where  even  the  final  cut  is 
largely  firewood.  The  tendency  at  present  is  for  heavier  thinnings 
and  a  larger  return  from  this  source.  In  pine  (Schwappach,  p.  5) 
the  thinnings  in  1889  made  about  thirty-five  per  cent  of  the  total 
growth  while  in  1908  they  made  about  fifty  per  cent  and  the  same 
change  is  apparent  in  the  treatment  of  other  species. 

The  influence  of  site  on  thinnings  is  ilustrated  in  the  following 
figures  for  the  stand  of  pine  one  hundred  and  twenty  years  old : 


Main  or  final  cut, 

Sum  of  thinnings  during 

120  years  old. 

life  of  stand. 

Volume  cu.  ft. 

$  per  acre 

Volume  cu.  ft. 

$  per  acre 

Site  I 

6860 

774 

7540 

505 

Site  II 

5640 

600 

6650 

365 

Site  III 

4550 

368 

5340 

284 

Site  IV 

3620 

268 

3940 

203 

Site  V 

2760 

153 

2800 

136 

From  the  foregoing  figures  it  is  apparent  that  site  greatly  af- 
fects the  volume  and  value  of  thinnings  and  also  that  the  difference 
for  different  sites  corresponds  closely  to  that  of  the  final  stand. 

b.  The  influence  of  the  method  of  treatment  or  silviculture 
extends  beyond  the  mere  practice  of  thinning  itself.  A  dense  repro- 
duction like  good  stands  of  natural  reproduction,  or  dense  seeding 
and  planting,  call  for  early  thinning.  In  many  localities  even  in 
central  Europe  such  a  thinning  is  made  at  a  loss.  Thinnings  of  oak 
ten  years  old  from  usual  seeding,  also  thinnings  of  beech  and  even 
pine  and  spruce,  come  under  this  description.  Here  the  method,  if 
artificial,  by  wider  spacing  may  save  money  in  seeds  and  plants  and 
again  save  the  expense  of  early  thinnings,  besides  producing  larger 
material  in  the  same  period  of  time. 

The  mixed  forest,  especially  mixture  of  hardwoods  and  con- 
ifers, introduces  disadvantages  as  well  as  advantages,  with  the  for- 
mer still  prevailing.  Thinnings  of  mixed  stands  require  more  judg- 
ment and  care  and  generally  increase  the  difficulty  of  selling  the 
material.  In  hardwoods  like  ash,  hickory,  maple,  where  small  sec- 
ond growth  stuff  is  valuable  the  mixture  may  prove  an  advantage. 
As  stated  before,  the  greatest  differences  in  the  income  from  thin- 
nings rest  with  the  thinning  practice  itself.  Fifty  and  more  years 


48  FOREST  VALUATION 

ago  many  foresters  still  believed  in  the  dense  stand,  removed  only 
dead  and  dying  trees.  This  did  practically  nothing  to  stimulate  the 
growth  of  the  stand,  either  in  volume  or  quality,  and  did  not  relieve 
the  stand  of  the  struggle  between  individual  trees.  This  method 
furnished  very  little  of  value  in  thinnings  and  tended  to  produce 
smaller  timber  for  the  final  cut. 

As  indicated  by  Schwappach's  tables  the  modern  practice  is 
now  taking  out  as  much  volume  in  thinnings  as  is  expected  in  the 
final  cut  and  the  tendency  is  for  further  increase.  With  a  closer 
utilization  and  better  prices  for  small  stuff  it  seems  a  possibility  to 
increase  the  income  from  thinnings  and  in  pine,  oak  and  many  hard- 
woods, make  it  approach  closely  the  money  value  of  the  final  cut. 

3.  The  cost  of  reproduction,  c  of  the  formula,  varies  with  site 
species  and  methods  and  is  greatly  affected  by  enemies,  fungi,  in- 
sects, rodents,  also  by  season,  storm,  frost,  or  conditions  which  may 
not  be  classed,  ordinarily,  with  site.  From  a  business  point  of  view, 
as  expressed  in  the  income  value  of  the  land,  it  is  not  enough  that 
reproduction  may  be  accomplished  but  it  is  necessary  that  a  new 
stand  be  established  with  certainty  and  safety,  and  in  reasonable 
time.  Generally  natural  reproduction  is  considered  cheaper  than 
planting.  In  many  cases  this  is  true.  But  if  a  stand  of  beech  is 
opened  in  the  shelterwood  plan  and  has  perhaps  a  growth  of  less 
than  one  per  cent  in  value  with  only  about  one-half  cover  it  is  poor 
economy  to  wait  ten  years  and  more,  as  has  actually  been  done  even 
of  late  years,  for  natural  re-seeding.  In  some  cases  where  this  was 
observed  in  1910  the  land  readily  produces  from  four  to  seven  dol- 
lars worth  of  timber  per  acre  and  year  so  that  the  expense  of  ten 
years  waiting  would  plant  up  the  area  several  times. 

a.     Artificial  reproduction. 

Schwappach  in  his  tables  for  pine  uses  ten  dollars  per  acre  as 
cost  of  planting  on  site  I  and  V,  the  best  and  poorest  lands.  For 
sites  II  to  IV  he  uses  eight  dollars  per  acre.  The  higher  price  for 
site  I  is  due  to  the  troublesome  weeds  and  brush  which  come  into 
clear  cut  areas  on  good  land  and  usually  require  extra  work  to  keep 
down. 

Endres,  "Valuation,"  uses  twelve  dollars  per  acre  and  Schwap- 
pach ten  for  all  sites  in  spruce,  for  white  fir  Endres  uses  ten  dollars 
but  evidently  he  has  in  mind  that  much  of  this  is  reproduced  nat- 
urally. For  pine  Endres  follows  Schwappach  and  uses  ten  dollars, 
but  does  so  for  site  III  as  well  as  I.  For  beech,  where  again  arti- 
ficial and  natural  reproduction  are  both  employed  and  figures  for 
costs  are  mixed,  he  uses  five  dollars  per  acre.  Reproduction  of  oak 


COST  OF  ARTIFICIAL,  REPRODUCTION  49 

in  Germany  is  rather  costly  since  a  great  deal  of  protective  work, 
fencing,  etc.,  must  be  done  to  prevent  damage  from  game.  Yet  in 
oak,  as  in  beech  the  cost  varies  from  almost  nothing  in  good  natural 
reproduction  to  expensive  planting  of  large  transplants.  The  great- 
er part  of  oak  is  started  artificially  by  very  dense  seeding.  Schwap- 
pach  therefore  puts  reproduction  costs  in  oak  at  fifteen  dollars  per 
acre. 

For  the  state  forests  of  Wiirttemberg,  nearly  five  hundred 
thousand  acres,  with  sixty-nine  per  cent  conifers  and  forty  per  cent 
occupied  by  beech  and  white  fir  where  natural  reproduction  prevails, 
the  official  costs  of  reproduction  include :  drainage,  seeding,  whether 
in  the  open  or  to  assist  natural  reproduction,  planting  of  all  kinds 
as  well  as  maintenance  of  nurseries  and  purchase  of  seeds  and 
plants.  But  it  does  not  include  the  extra  expenses  in  logging  due 
to  methods  of  natural  reproduction,  an  item  which  would  require 
estimate  from  one  piece  of  work  to  the  next  and  so  far  is  never 
introduced  in  forest  statistics.  The  following  is  taken  from  Graner, 
for  1908: 

Total  expense  for  reproduction  $129,000,  or  26  cents  per  acre 
of  forest,  of  this  total  there  was  for  (round  numbers)  : 

1.  Ditching    $  noo 

2.  Seeding,  new,  I'SQ  acres,  corrections  40  acres,  cost  per  acre 
$10.30,  total  2000 

3.  Planting,  new  plantations  4430  acres,  corrections  1130,  cost 

per  acre  $10.03,  cost  per  1000  plants  set  out,  $3.30,  total 55800 

4.  (Maintenance  of  nurseries,  500  acres   49100 

Cost  of  restocking  lands  or  reproduction  forms  only  seven 
per  cent  of  all  expenses  as  against  12  per  cent  spent  for  roads  in 
1908. 

The  high  cost  of  seeding  is  due  to  the  large  proportion  of  oak. 
In  the  pineries  of  Prussia  reproduction  by  artificial  seeding  has  been 
revived  by  Splettstosser  and  the  cost  in  some  cases  is  less  than  a 
dollar  and  a  half  an  acre.  But  in  dry  years  this  method  fails  and  the 
cost  of  successful  reproduction  by  seeding  is  still  uncertain  and 
greater  than  is  usually  assumed. 

For  the  state  forests  of  Prussia  reproduction  costs  in  1900 
were  about  twenty-seven  cents  per  acre  of  forest.  These  expenses 
have  increased  from  about  nine  cents  in  1870. 

In  the  Saxony  state  forests  the  average  costs  for  restocking 
were  about  twenty  cents  per  acre  of  forest,  including  ditching  work, 
having  approximately  doubled  since  1870. 


50  FORKST  VALUATION 

In  the  United  States  the  cost  of  planting  and  seeding  is  very 
variable.  In  the  eastern  states  for  conifers  and  most  native  hard- 
woods it  may  be  figured  approximately : 

Cost  of  raising  plants:  three  year  seedlings — $i  per  1,000;  four 
year  transplants,  or  2-2  plants,  $3  per  1,000;  to  set  out  either  coni- 
fers or  hardwoods  about  $4  per  i,ooa  Since  1,060  per  acre  is  quite 
sufficient,  the  cost  per  acre  is  $5  to  $7.  To  this  must  be  added  thirty 
to  fifty  per  cent  for  mishaps,  bringing  the  cost  per  acre  to  $7 — $10, 
or  about  the  same  as  the  cost  in  Europe,  where,  however,  much 
denser  planting  is  practiced.  For  oak  and  beech  about  two  to  five 
bushels  of  seed  per  acre  is  used.  With  acorns  at  a  dollar  and  a 
half,  a  common  price,  the  seeding  costs  about  $10  or  $12  per  acre. 
These  figures  vary  with  site,  labor,  cost  of  seed,  etc.,  and  will 
be  high  wherever  conditions  are  adverse  to  forest  growth  and  call 
for  extra  effort.  The  experience  of  the  United  States  Forest  Ser- 
vice though  the  most  extensive  in  this  country  can  not  well  be  used 
here,  since  the  conditions  under  which  most  of  this  work  has  been 
done  so  far  are  very  difficult,  particularly  as  regards  site,  accessi- 
bility, cost  of  labor,  and,  in  many  lacalities,  the  work  of  seeding 
suffered  excessively  through  rodents,  which  make  this  method  al- 
most useless.  Experience  in  district  i,  Montana,  etc.,  indicates  that 
even  here  the  cost  of  "effective"  or  successful  planting  is  now  close 
to  $11  per  acre,  and  that  much  planting  is  done  at  about  $7  per 
acre,  and  seeding  at  about  $2.50  per  acre  in  conifers.  But  it  should 
be  added  here  that  seeding  has  generally  been  a  failure  in  these 
western  forests  and  is  largely  abandoned. 
b.  Natural  reproduction. 

The  cost  of  natural  reproduction  is  assumed  to  be  zero.  This 
is  not  true  in  most  cases.  If  natural  reproduction  is  slow  it  wastes 
valuable  time,  years  of  rent  are  lost.  If  it  produces  a  stand  in 
which  a  portion  of  the  trees  are  of  poor  species  and  not  wanted  and 
this  condition  requires  the  cutting  out  of  material  at  a  loss,  this 
expense  may  very  well  be  charged  to  the  form  of  reproduction.  And 
even  where  the  natural  reproduction  is  perfect  as  to  species  and  time, 
but  produces  dense  thickets  of  stuff  which  cause  extra  expense  by 
early  thinning  or  involve  years  of  struggle  and  consequent  loss  of 
growth,  the  method  is  certainly  not  without  cost  to  the  owner  of  the 
forest.  Unfortunately  statistics  on  these  points  are  still  too  im- 
perfect to  base  general  statements  on.  The  universal  adoption  of 
clear  cutting  and  planting  in  pine  and  spruce  in  German  and  other 
forests  is  the  best  wholesale  evidence  that  natural  reproduction  in- 
volves expense,  or,  what  is  the  same  thing,  that  artificial  reproduc- 


COST  OF  NATURAL  REPRODUCTION  51 

tion  saves  money.  Similarly,  when  the  best  Danish  foresters  find 
it  to  their  advantage  to  spend  fifteen  or  twenty  dollars  in  tilling, 
liming  and  artificial  seeding  to  assist  so-called  natural  reproduction, 
we  have  here  artificial  seeding  and  the  old  stand  is  useful  only  as 
shelter. 

In  good  coppice  on  good. sites  the  expense  of  cleaning  out  use- 
less sprouts  and  useless  species  is  small  and  if  need  be  can  be  neg- 
lected. But  such  saving  is  poor  business  on  excellent  site  which 
should  produce  from  ten  to  twelve  dollars  worth  of  good  material 
per  acre  and  year. 

In  selection  forest  of  our  ordinary  hardwoods  natural  repro- 
duction is  quite  certain,  fairly  prompt,  but  often  made  up  of  the  less 
desirable  species  and  either  means  a  loss  in  the  yield  or  an  expense 
for  cutting  out  this  material. 

In  situations  where  a  dry  climate,  lack  of  seed,  etc.,  prevent 
prompt  reproduction,  the  waste  by  having  a  part  of  the  land  unused 
for  years  may  be  a  very  considerable  expense,  as  pointed  out  above. 

In  nearly  all  cases,  except  coppice,  natural  reproduction  in- 
creases the  cost  of  logging.  In  many  cases  in  central  Europe  today 
this  amounts  to  more  than  twice  the  cost  of  planting  and  should  be 
charged  to  reproduction  and  not  deducted  from  the  final  yield  as  is 
always  done. 

In  remote  mountainous  districts  where  the  cold  climate  retards 
growth  and  the  site  at  best  produces  but  a  small  yield,  lodge  pole, 
Engelman  spruce,  tamarack  in  swamp,  jack  pine,  etc.,  the  cost  of 
artificial  reproduction  may  not  be  warranted  except  perhaps  as  a 
starter  on  burned  over  districts,  and  here  the  natural  reproduction 
in  spite  of  its  loss  in  time  and  rent  may  still  be  the  only  economical 
method.  And  even  on  better  sites  in  our  unsettled  districts,  western 
yellow  pine,  etc.,  with  enormous  masses  of  excellent  but  unsalable 
material,  natural  reproduction  may  be  indicated.  But  to  leave  large 
areas  of  these  better  sites  entirely  bare  for  many  years  would  be  a 
mistake.  This  is  recognized  so  that  even  now  planting  is  being 
started  in  many  localities. 

4.  Current  expenses,  e,  usually  consist  of  administration  and 
protection,  improvements  and  taxes. 

a.  Taxes  are  beyond  the  control  of  the  owner ;  they  are  known 
and  remain  fairly  constant  for  large  rural  properties  for  many 
years.  In  the  United  States  under  ordinary  settled  conditions  rural 
property  pays  about  six  or  eight  dollars  on  the  thousand  dollars 
worth  of  property  or  about  twelve  dollars  on  a  two-thirds  valuation. 


52  FOREST  VALUATION 

This  will  no  doubt  remain  so  whether  forest  taxation  continues  on 
the  present  plan  or  changes  to  a  yield  tax  or  single  tax,  for  in  the 
end  the  income  or  the  income  value  of  the  forest  determines  the 
ability  of  the  owner  to  pay. 

b.  Administration  and  protection  are  usually  given  together  in 
recent  statistics.     Endres,  "Valuation"  p.  38,  quotes  the  following 
for  the  state  forests  of  Germany:    Prussia,  Bavaria  and  Alsace- 
Lorain  about  seventy  cents  per  acre ;  Baden  eighty-six  cents,  Wurt- 
temberg  one  dollar  and  five  cents  and  Saxony  one  dollar  and  thirty- 
five  cents  per  acre.     Usually  about  sixty  per  cent  of  this  goes  for 
administration  proper  and  the  rest  for  protection.     Since  so  much 
of  the  under-forester's  or  ranger's  time  is  spent  in  work  where  pro- 
tection and  supervision  is  combined  it  is  impracticable  to  separate 
the  two.     It  is  doubtful,  however,  if  protection  proper  is  done  for 
less  than  twenty  cents  per  acre  in  any  of  these  state  forests.     Ac- 
cording to  Schwappach,  the  larger  private  estates  in  south  Germany 
spend  about  forty-five  or  sixty-five  cents  per  acre  and  year  for  ad- 
ministration" and  protection. 

In  the  United  States  there  are  no  satisfactory,  comparable  fig- 
ures on  this  point.  The  total  appropriation  for  the  care  of  approx- 
imately one  hundred  and  sixty  million  acres  of  national  forests  is 
only  about  five  million  dollars  or  three  cents  per  acre.,  a  figure  which 
can  not  be  considered  here  for  it  does  not  even  indicate  a  reasonable 
interest  in  the  property.  Of  this  three  cents  it  is  assumed  that  about 
two  cents  an  acre  are  devoted  to  administration  and  protection.  But 
everything  is  new ;  a  large  amount  of  labor  is  absolutely  necessary 
to  survey,  locate,  map  and  describe  or  record  things,  to  enable  any 
administration  to  be  carried  on  at  all,  and  in  addition  much  work  is 
necessary  to  attend  to  the  orderly  disposition  of  timber,  grazing,  etc., 
so  that  it  is  doubtful  if  much  more  than  one  cent  an  acre  is  actually 
devoted  to  protection  and  supervision. 

It  is  difficult,  as  yet,  to  estimate  what  will  constitute  a  satisfac- 
factory  figure  for  administration  and  protection  in  our  extensive 
enterprises.  Recent  experience  would  indicate  that  protection  of 
the  kind  that  will  really  protect  can  not  be  furnished  under  ten  cents 
an  acre ;  about  half  this  sum  should  be  allowed  for  administration 
if  the  property  is  to  be  properly  regulated,  inspected  and  its  busi- 
ness recorded.  Undue  economy  in  either  direction  is  costly. 

c.  Improvements  in  forest  properties  consist  chiefly  in  roads 
and  besides  these  in  buildings  for  foresters  and  rangers,  and  in  tele- 
phone lines.     Occasionally  special  improvements  like  chutes,  flumes, 
etc.,  are  provided,  but  they  may  well  be  charged  to  exploitation  and 
deducted  from  the  gross  yield. 


CURRENT  EXPENSES  53 

For  the  most  part  improvements  are  developed  gradually  and 
the  expense  for  improvement  is  fitted  to  the  income,  and  may  there- 
fore remain  fairly  constant  for  a  long  term  of  years.  In  the  state 
forests  of  Europe  the  construction  and  maintenance  of  roads  is 
usually  the  only  item  quoted  in  the  reports.  In  the  state  forests 
of  Wiirttemberg  road  work  in  the  five  years  ending  1908,  averaged 
about  forty  cents  per  acre  of  forest  and  of  this  twenty-four  cents 
was  for  maintenance.  Ever  since  1875  tne  roads  have  received  over 
twenty-five  cents  per  acre  and  year,  and  while  new  construction  will 
become  less  in  time  the  item  of  roads  will  always  amount  to  over 
thirty  cents  per  acre  and  year. 

In  the  United  States  there  is  as  yet  little  experience  in  this  mat- 
ter outside  the  United  States  Forest  Service  and  as  stated,  the  Ser- 
vice has  had  too  little  support  to  do  more  than  make  a  beginning. 

On  a  good  forest  property  with  satisfactory  market,  etc.,  a 
suitable  road  system  is  a  necessity  and  it  is  reasonable  to  suppose 
that  this  will  cost  here  what  it  does  abroad. 

Combining  the  factors  of  current  expenses  for  our  conditions 
the  following  estimate  will  suit  a  large  part  of  our  forests : 

Taxes    15  cents  per  acre 

Protection    10  cents  per  acre 

Administration     5  cents  per  acre 

Improvements    10  cents  per  acre 

Total    40  cents  per  acre 

This  should  be  regarded  rather  as  minimum  than  average  for  good, 
intensive  work. 

That  these  expenses  must  be  suited  to  the  income  or  the  value 
of  the  crop  which  any  tract  can  produce  is  evident.  From  the  for- 
mula it  is  apparent  that:  Yr  -f-  Ta  (i.opr"a)  must  be  greater  than 
c  (i.opr)  +E  (i.opr—  i). 

If  we  take  the  value  of  the  thinnings,  prolonged,  to  be  equal 
to  one  half  Yr  or  the  final  cut,  and  use  ten  dollars  for  planting  and 
forty  cents  for  current  expenses,  eighty  years  as  rotation  and  figure 
with  three  per  cent,  then  the  final  cut  must  be  worth  more  than  one 
hundred  and  seventy-five  dollars  to  produce  any  rent  on  the  land. 
In  jack  pine,  tamarack,  or  high  mountain  timber  where  the  final  cut 
can  not  be  expected  to  be  worth  over  fifty  dollars  and  in  the  moun- 
tain forest  requires  perhaps  one  hundred  and  fifty  years  to  grow, 


54 


FOREST  VALUATION 


it  is  evident  that  planting  should  be  avoided  and  the  current  expenses 
cut  to  one  half  or  less  of  the  above  estimate. 

5.  The  rotation  is  largey  a  matter  of  species,  site  and  market 
and  also  of  treatment.  The  first  condition  is  to  produce  material 
which  can  be  sold  at  fair  price  and  in  large  quantities.  Generally, 
then,  the  market  determines  the  size  and  quality  while  site,  species 
and  method  determine  the  time  required  to  produce  the  demanded 
size  and  quality. 

In  central  Europe  oak  requires  over  one  hundred  and  fifty  years, 
pine  saw  timber  and  beech  over  one  hundred  and  twenty,  while 
spruce  and  balsam  are  now  commonly  cut  at  about  one  hundred 
years. 

The  following  figures  of  age,  class,  conditions  for  the  timber 
forests  of  all  Germany  are  instructive  in  this  connection : 

Area  in  1,000  acres  of  different  age  classes  in  1900. 


Over 

100 

80-100 

60-80 

40-60 

20-40 

to  20 

bare 

years. 

Oak 

244 

147 

181 

208 

250 

272 

25 

Beech 

792 

823 

937 

816 

657 

5ii 

•  29 

Pine 

975 

H33 

1801 

2859 

3319 

3383 

53 

Spruce 

403 

548 

875 

1191 

1517 

1517 

17 

White  fir 

150 

118 

120 

108 

122 

116 

15 

Larch 

o-3 

1.6 

5 

8 

7 

9 

— 

From  a  financial  standpoint  the  temptation  is  to  set  a  rotation 
producing  the  largest  Se  or  largest  interest  rate  on  the  business. 

For  spruce  in  Saxony  state  forests  according  to  Schulze,  the 
following  is  true  with  present  prices : 

Rotation  50-60  years,  rate  .made    5     % 

60-70  3-7% 

70-80  3.2% 

80-90  2.6% 

90-100  2.2% 


But  if  a  rotation  of  fifty  to  sixty  years  was  attempted  on  all 
Saxon  state  forest  lands  the  price  of  smaller  sizes  would  drop  and 
the  result  would  be  a  failure.  Again,  for  large  areas  of  poor  sites, 
IV  and  V,  such  a  rotation  would  not  produce  marketable  stuff  at  all. 


INFLUENCE;  OF  INTEREST  RATE  55 

In  fact,  according  to  the  same  author,  a  rotation  of  fifty-five 
or  sixty-five  years  is  most  profitable,  even  with  present  prices,  on 
only  eleven  per  cent  of  all  forests,  while  the  rest  require,  owing  to 
slower  growth,  rotations  of  over  sixty-five  and  as  high  as  one  hun- 
dred. 

With  better  machinery,  manufacture  of  pulp  and  extensive  use 
of  timber  in  mining,  etc.,  the  use  of  smaller  sizes  has  been  increased. 
In  conifers  timber  ten  to  fourteen  inches  d.b.h.  with  bark  can  be 
sold  at  good  price  and  in  largest  quantities.  In  addition  the  modern 
practice  of  thinning  gives  more  space  to  each  tree,  stimulates  growth 
and  so  produces  these  sizes  in  shorter  time.  Accordingly,  there  is 
a  tendency  toward  shorter  rotations  in  all  timber  except  oak,  where 
satisfactory  quality  requires  trees  over  eighteen  inches  d.b.h.  In 
the  United  States  the  timber  industries  are  rapidly  adapting  them- 
selves to  the  use  of  smaller  sizes  so  that,  locally,  at  least,  as  small 
stuff  is  sawed  and  worked  up  as  in  Europe.  In  the  handling  of  de- 
fective stuff  the  United  States  methods  far  excell  those  of  the  old 
world.  It  is  reasonable,  therefore,  to  assume  that  the  conditions  de- 
termining the  rotation  will  be  the  same  here  as  abroad.  With  warm- 
er climate  and  better  growth,  shorter  rotations  such  as  fifty  years 
even  for  saw  timber  are  anticipated,  established  or  accepted  in  legis- 
lation, in  Massachusetts  and  Connecticut.  In  loblolly  pine,  hard- 
woods in  river  bottoms,  etc.,  no  doubt  this  will  apply,  but  in  all  cases 
the  quality  of  "grain,"  fine  or  broad  rings,  will  also  be  considered 
by  the  market  and  may  call  for  denser  stands  and  longer  time. 

6.  The  interest  rate,  p,  has  been  discussed  before.  Its  effect 
on  calculation  of  the  income  value  of  the  land  and  of  the  success  of 
the  forest  business  is  very  great.  The  interest  rate  actually  made 
in  the  foresj  business  in  the  state  forests  of  Germany  varies  from 
two  to  three  per  cent  on  the  sale  value  of  the  property.  An  interest 
rate  of  five  per  cent  will  probably  prove  ninety  per  cent  of  European 
forestry  a  failure.  In  the  United  States  at  present  and  for  some 
time  to  come  the  unsettled  conditions  of  values  in  timber  and  tim- 
ber lands  will  make  it  possible  to  acquire  lands  at  prices  which  will 
assure  higher  rates.  In  time  the  real  value  of  land  and  timber  will 
approach  the  true  income  value  and  the  interest  rate  made  in  the 
business  will  be  normal  just  as  it  is  in  agriculture  and  other  lines  of 
business.  To  make  these  calculations  reasonable,  comparable  and 
useful  it  would  be  well  if  a  uniform  rate  could  be  adopted  and  since 
three  per  cent  has  been  used  extensively  in  European  works  it  com- 
mends itself  for  adoption  here. 


FOREST  VALUATION 


c.     Actual  values  of  Se. 

The  following  figures  are  taken  from  Endres'  Valuation,  and 
Schwappach's  Tables  of  Growth.  The  interest  rate  is  three  per  cent. 

Income  or  expectation  value  of  land  per  acre  for  different  spe- 
cies and  rotations. 


Spruce 

White  fir 

Pine 

Beech 

Rotation 

on  sites 

on 

sites 

on  sites 

on  sites 

years 

I 

II 

III 

I 

III 

I 

III 

1 

III 

dollars  per  acre 

30 

51 

10 

—14 

—  10 

—30 

43 

3 

4 

—19 

40 

100 

47 

13 

67 

—5 

59 

7 

25 

—4 

50 

139 

77 

38 

134 

25 

66 

13 

32 

6 

60 

159 

98 

53 

156 

38 

67 

13 

35 

7 

70 

166 

105 

59 

156 

44 

64 

v    13 

35 

7 

80 

161 

105 

59 

145 

44 

59 

10 

34 

4 

00 

151 

99 

56 

130 

4i 

53 

8 

31 

2 

100 

138 

91 

51 

114 

36 

48 

5 

27 

2 

no 

126 

83 

46 

99 

30 

43 

4 

24 

—  2 

1  20 

117 

75 

4i 

86 

25 

40 

2 

21 

—4 

For  white  oak  in  Germany  two  per  cent,  the  values  are  as  fol- 
lows for  Se: 


Rotation,  years 

Site  I 

Site  II 

Site  III 

IOO 

$262 

$131 

$56 

1  20 

272 

133 

63 

140 

260 

134 

•60 

IOO 

236 

124 

53 

180 

215 

H3 

49 

200 

201 

101 

44 

The  above  figures  are  based  on  normal  yield  tables  of  Schwap- 
pach  for  spruce,  pine  and  oak,  Eichorn,  1902,  for  white  fir,  and 
Grundner,  1904,  for  beech.  They  asume  cost  of  reproduction  twelve 
dollars  per  acre  for  spruce,  ten  for  fir  and  pine,  five  for  beech  and 
fifteen  for  oak.  The  current  expenses  are  taken  at  ninety  cents  per 
acre  and  year  for  all  but  oak  where  sixty  cents  is  used.  Since  the 
above  values  are  based  on  normal  yield  tables,  assuming  full  and  sat- 
isfactory stands,  the  values  require  reduction  in  practice  by  at  least 


APPRECIATION  OF  SE)  57 

the  amount  by  which  the  practice  now  fails  to  keep  the  forest  in 
fully  stocked  good  growing  condition.  This  for  the  state  forests  of 
WKirttemberg  would  be  less  than  thirty  per  cent,  and  for  most  state 
forests  would  vary  from  thirty  to  forty  per  cent. 

An  examination  of  values  for  Se  at  three  and  two  per  cent  re- 
veals the  interesting  fact  that  the  maximum  for  Se  comes  too  early 
at  three  per  cent,  and  of  course  still  earlier  at  higher  rates,  for  a 
safe  technical  rotation  which  works  for  the  sizes  most  demanded 
by  the  present  market.  On  a  basis  of  two  per  cent  the  maximum 
Se  and  the  best  technical  rotation  fairly  coincide  for  all  species  ex- 
cept oak  where  even  two  per  cent  brings  maximum  Se  too  early  by 
at  least  forty  years.  This  seems  to  indicate  clearly  that  the  true 
value  growth  of  the  forest  is  about  two  per  cent  for  pine  and  spruce 
and  below  two  per  cent  or  about  one  and  one-half  for  white  oak  in 
the  German  forest  and  present  conditions  of  market. 

On  the  other  hand  a  two  per  cent  rate  makes  forest  lands  gen- 
erally more  valuable  than  farm  lands  of  far  better  quality  for  all 
species  except  oak.  In  oak  even  a  two  per  cent  rate  gives  to  the  land 
no  higher  value  than  the  same  land  would  have  for  farming. 

d.  Appreciation  of  the  calculation  of  the  income  value  of 
the  land. 

According  to  Endres,  von  Zanthiers  articles  in  Stahl's  Forst- 
magazin,  1764,  may  be  considered  the  earliest  satisfactory  efforts  to 
develop  money  yield  tables  and  a  calculation  by  which  different 
methods  may  be  compared. 

The  first  calculation  of  the  income  value  of  the  soil  was  pub- 
lished by  Konig  in  his  Anleitnng  zur  Holztaxation,  1813.  His  for- 
mula agrees  with  the  present  except  that  he  used  c  in  place  of 

c(i.opr) 


The  formula  as  now  used  was  first  developed  by  Faustman  in 
1849  m  tne  Allgemeine  I'orst  und  fagdseitung,  under  the  title  Wald- 
bodenrentenformel,  formula  of  soil  rent  in  forest. 

The  formula  has  been  and  is  still  being  attacked  in  spite  of  the 
fact  that  the  basis  for  the  calculation,  final  cut  and  thinnings,  cost 
of  planting  and  current  expenses  are  well  known,  the  values,  yield 
tables,  etc.,  constantly  used,  and  universally  accepted  as  the  best 
there  is,  and  as  being  as  reliable  as  any  similar  compilations  in  other 


58  FOREST  VALUATION 

lines  of  business.    The  calculation  itself  as  a  simple  problem  in  arith- 
metic is  no  longer  discussed. 

Usually  the  criticism  is  one  of  the  three  following : 

a.  Forest'valuation,  in  Germany,  does  not  ordinarily  start  with 
bare  land  but  with  a  forest  business  fairly  regulated  for  a  long  time. 
There  is  no  .deed  of  any  compound  interest  calculation.    This  argu- 
ment seems  convincing  but  is  not  true.     In  modern  forest  practice, 
excepting  selection  forest,  every  acre  of  forest  is  cut  once  in  each 
rotation.    Whether  this  is  done  in  clear  cutting  in  a  single  year  or 
in  shelterwood  in  several  years,  the  land  is  cleared  of  the  old  timber 
and  a  new  stand  is  started.    To  start  this  stand  and  care  for  it  dur- 
ing eighty  or  a  hundred  years  costs  money  and  when  the  stand  is  ripe, 
the  question  is :  what  has  it  cost  to  produce  ?   Since  the  money  spent 
in  planting,  protection,  administration,  taxes,  etc.,  has  not  paid  any 
interest  it  is  proper  that  this  interest  be  compounded  yearly  and 
charged  to  the  cost  of  producing  the  stand  exactly  as  is  done  in  the 
above  calculation  for  Se. 

b.  The  second  criticism  is  that  the  values  for  final  yield  and 
thinnings  are  useless,  since  timber  prices  advance  so  rapidly  that 
they  may  double  and  more  during  one  rotation.     This  argument  is 
valid  but  it  does  not  affect  the  case  at  all.     If  a  man  examines  two 
farms  with  a  view  to  buying,  he  is  apt  to  judge  on  a  basis  of  present 
prices  and  if  one  farm  produces  thirty  bushels  of  corn  per  acre  and 
the  other  fifty  bushels  he  will  consider  that  the  latter  is  worth  more 
than  the  former.    And  he  will  be  right  regardless  of  any  change  in 
the  price  of  corn.     Exactly  the  same  thing  is  true  in  forestry.     If 
Faustman  applied  his  calculation  to  two  tracts  of  forestland  sixty 
years  ago  and  found  one  of  them  worth  twice  as  much  as  the  other 
the  important  point  in  his  calculation  is  still  valid  in  spite  of  the  fact 
that  timber  has  doubled  in  value  during  this  time.    And  even  the  ab- 
solute value  was,  for  his  purpose,  entirely  right,  for  no  one. is  willing 
to  buy  a  farm  or  forest  on  the  assumption  that  in  one  hundred  years 
the  crops  will  be  worth  double  the  price.     Occasionally  there  are 
cases  where  an  advance  in  price  is  practically  certain  and  may  well 
be  introduced  even  in  calculation  of  the  business.     For  instance  a 
plantation  of  pine  set  out  today  in  the  eastern  United  States  may 
take  eighty  years  to  mature  and  will  then  certainly  not  be  sold  at 
present  stumpage  prices.    But  even  in  such  a  case  it  is  not  necessary 
or  desirable  to  assume  uncertain  advances  in  prices  and  most  men 
would  prefer  to  estimate  the  value  of  their  enterprise  on  the  basis  of 
present  prices,  using,  no  doubt,  maximum  rather  than  average  fig- 
ures. 


CRITICISM  OF  S3  59 

c.  The  third  criticism  is  that  the  calculation  is  a  failure  as  soon 
as  "reasonable''  or  "current"  rates  of  interest  are  employed.  This 
point  has  been  discussed  under  "Rates  of  interest."  As  pointed 
out,  current  rates  of  interest  are  normally  far  above  what  large  in-, 
dustries  and  business  actually  make.  On  the  basis  of  six  per  cent 
farming  in  the  United  States  is  a  losing  business,  though  the  farmer 
pays  this  as  a  current  rate.  The  forests  and  their  growth  depend 
on  natural  laws  and  have  nothing  to  do  with  interest  rates.  The 
only  use  of  an  interest  rate  in  the  study  of  these  forests  and  their^ 
growth  is  to  serve  as  a  measure.  We  can  use  five  per  cent  and  have 
all  values  of  Se  negative  and  still  secure  a  very  good  comparison 
between  dififerentjracts  of  land,  between  differe"nt  species  and  meth- 
ods of  treatment.  But  these  negative  values  while  making  possible 
this  comparison  will  give  a  distorted  picture  of  things ;  they  will  tell 
the_  triith  and  yetjpislead.  The  absolute  values  will  be  correct  so 
far  as  the  five  per  cent  basis  goes  but  they  will  show  a  good  safe 
business  bringing  in  millions  and  giving  paying  employment  to 
thousands  as  being  a  losing  enterprise. 

This  same  criticism  was  amplified  by  pointing  out  that  this  form 
of  calculation  on  a  basis  of  ordinary  interest  rates  would  lead  to  a 
ridiculous  and  disastrous  shortening  of  rotation.  In  part  this  was 
provoked  by  enthusiasts  in  mathematics  who  actually  argued  for 
such  shortening  of  rotation.  That  shorter  rotations  were  needed 
most  authorities  agreed  but  rotations  of  forty  or  fifty  years  in  spruce, 
etc.,  were  evidently  wrong  and  the  practitioner  saw  this.  The  mis- 
take was  one  of  judgment  in  establishing  the  value,  of  timber.  As 
stated  under  rotation,  the  maximum  Se  for  Saxon  spruce  with  pres- 
ent prices  would  come  at  about  fifty  years.  At  present  the  great 
body  of  timber  offered  to  the  market  is  larger  than  is  produced  in 
fifty  years  and  the  prices  of  the  smaller,  less  useful  stuff  are  pur- 
posely kept  up  by  not  offering  too  much  of  this  kind  of  material. 
If  the  Saxon  state  forest  should  go  to  a  fifty  year  rotation  this 
small  stuff  would  at  once  become  a  drug  on  the  market  and  what 
seemed  profitable  would  prove  a  loss. 

But  this  merely  proves  that  in  deciding  on  the  proper  rotation 
and  consequent  final  yield,  it  is  necessary  to  use  some  judgment  and 
consider  the  demands  of  the  market. 

Good  material,  clean  stuff,  fourteen  inches  in  spruce,  etc.,  need 
not  fear  depression  in  prices.  Its  market  is  practically  unlimited  in 
central  Europe  and  therefore  the  rotation  is  set  to  produce  this  ma- 
terial. 

The  calculation  of  the  income  value  of  the  land  devoted  to  for- 
est is  not  mere  formula,  in  fact  the  formula  may  well  be  dispensed 


60  FOREST  VALUATION 

with,  it  is  an  analysis  of  value  such  as  is  used  in  other  lines  of  bus- 
iness. The  estimate  of  value  or  the  assessment  of  every  farm  in- 
volves this  same  analysis  and  the  only  difference  lies  in  the  time  eie- 
ment,  a  peculiarity  of  the  forest  business. 

Just  as  the  forester  uses  yield  tables,  expenses  of  starting  the 
crop,  caring  for  this  crop,  taxes,  improvements,  etc.,  so  the  farmer 
has  accepted  standard  figures  for  costs  of  plowing,  seeding,  culti- 
vating, his  "stock  figures"  or  yield  tables,  and  finally  his  average 
prices  which  guide  him  in  setting  a  value  on  the  land,  on  different 
crops  and  methods. 

e.  The  Se  in  coppice  woods. 

Since  in  ordinary  coppice  the  crop  is  cut  clean  and  the  ground 
cleared  there  is  a  temptation  to  use  the  calculation  for  Se  without 
any  allowance  and  put  cost  of  reproduction  equal  to  zero.  This  is 
not  correct  for  a  piece  of  coppice  woods  recently  cut  is  not  bare  land, 
but  bare  land  plus  living  stumps.  These  stumps  are  the  equivalent 
of  a  good  plantation  safely  established  and  so  have  value. 

f.  The  Se  in  the  selection  forest. 

Here  the  crop  is  never  entirely  removed.  Where  the  forest  has 
been  in  use  for  a  long  time  and  satisfactory  records  of  growth  have 
been  established  the  stumpage  value  of  the  material  removed  during 
one  rotation  and  properly  prolonged  may  be  substituted  for  Yr  -j- 
5  Ta  (i.opr'a)  in  the  usual  calculation. 

In  most  cases  it  is  simpler  to  estimate  the  Yr,  etc.,  from  the 
size,  quality  and  growth  of  the  timber  found  upon  the  land  at  any 
time  and  make  up  a  new  case, 


F.     VALUE  OF  STAND  OF  TIMBER  OR  THE  GROWING 
STOCK  IN  THE  EVEN-AGED  STAND. 

A  stand  of  white  pine  now  fifty  years  old  may  be  sold  without 
the  land  to  a  man  who  intends  cutting  the  timber  at  once.  In  a 
neighborhood  in  New  Hampshire  where  many  such  stands  are  cat 
every  year,  this  kind  of  a  stand  will  have  a  fairly  definite  market- 
or  sale  value. 

Stands  of  white  pine  in  this  same  vicinity  but  less  than  thirty 
years  old  would  probably  have  no  ready  market  and  there  would  be 
no  established  or  accepted  sale  value,  while  there  would  be  leady 
sale  value  for  any  stand  over  fifty  years  old.  Under  ordinary  con- 
ditions stands  not  yet  ready  for  use.  non-merchantable  or  immature, 


VALUE)  OF  GROWING  STOCK  6 1 

have  no  regular  sale  value  and  this  is  true  even  of  stands  abroad, 
for  the  sale  of  such  stands  is  not  sufficiently  common,  even  there. 

The  same  stand  may  be  sold  to  a  man  who  wants  to  keep  it 
until  it  is  seventy  years  old  and  of  better  size  and  quality.  He  would 
have  considerable  expense  holding  the  stand ;  interest  on  the  money 
he  has  to  pay  for  the  stand,  rent  to  the  owner  of  the  land  ,  care  and 
protection  for  twenty  years  and  taxes  for  this  period.  To  determine 
what  he  could  pay  for  the  stand  he  would  assume  a  certain  value 
wThich  the  stand  is  expected  to  have  at  seventy  years,  deduct  all  ex- 
penses and  find  what  he  may  expect  to  get  at  the  end  of  twenty 
years  when  the  stand  is  cut.  He  would  discount  this  to  present  date 
and  get  the  present  value  of  the  stand  on  the  basis  of  his  expecta- 
tions. This  would  be  the  expectation  value  of  the  stand. 

The  owner  who  wishes  to  sell  the  stand  would  set  the  price 
first  of  all  by  the  amount  which  it  has  cost  to  produce  the  stand,  by 
the  cost  value  of  the  stand.  This  cost  value  of  an  even-aged,  plant- 
ed stand  he  can  determine  exactly  as  the  farmer  finds  the  cost  of 
producing  an  acre  of  corn.  He  charges  the  expense  of  planting,  the 
rent  on  the  land,  taxes  and  care.  But  unlike  the  farmer  he  has  to 
charge  and  compound  these  sums  for  the  whole  fifty  years  or  the 
age  of  the  stand. 

Any  stand  of  timber  regardless  of  age  or  size  has  the  usual 
three  values,  cost,  sale  and  expectation,  with  the  sale  value  rather 
indefinite  for  non-merchantable  stands. 

a.  Sale  value  of  growing  stock. 

Since  this  is  largely  a  matter  of  stumpage  of  marketable  stuff 
either  for  immediate  use  or  to  hold  for  future  use,  and  since  in  the 
United  States  this  is  important  chiefly  in  connection  with  our  wild 
woods,  it  is  discussed  under  stumpage  value  in  chapter  VI. 

b.  Cost  value  of  growing  stock. 

The  usual  case  for  an  even-aged  stand  of  timber  is  as  follows : 
i.     Area. of  stand,  80  acres;  age,  m,  45  years,  interest  rate,  p, 

2%.  \p-V. 

Premises  per  acre : 

Cost  value  of  land,  Sc,  $5,  therefore  rent  Sc  (.op)  is  ten  cents. 

Cost  of  planting,  c,  $8. 

Current  expenses  yearly,  e,  50  cents. 

Income  from  thinnings : 

Thinning  at  age  of  20  years,  Ta,  costs  $3,  negative  income, 
30  Tb,  just  paid  for  cutting, 

40  Tc,  5  cords  of  wood  worth  $10. 


62  FORKST  VALUATTON 

2.  Expenses  incurred  to  produce  the  stand  or  grow  it  to  the 
age  of  45  years : 

Cost  of  planting  prolonged,  c  (i.opm), 

or   8    (i.024"') $  19.40 

Current  yearly  expenses  e  with  intere'st. 

e(iQpm— i  =E(       m_o  where  E=   _e_ 
i. op — i  .op 

'y\l   „ 
and  yearly  rent  of  land  with  interest, 

rent0'0""-0     »Si(i.op--i), 

i. op— i 

simplifying  (E-fS>c)    (i.op™ — i)  or 

(25  +  5)  (i.0245— i)     $  43. 13 

Thinning  at  age  of  20  years,  cost  with  interest. 

Ta(i.op'"-a)  =  3(i-0225)     4-92 

Total  expenses  per  acre   $  67.45 

3.  Income  per  acre  obtained   from  the  stand  during  the  45 
years, 

Thinning  at  30  (just  paid  expense) $    o 

Thinning  at  40,  $10  with  interest  for  five  years 11.04 

Total    income    $11.04 

4.  Net  cost  per  acre: 

$67.45  — $11. 04  =  $56.41 

and  cost  value  of  the  stand  of  80  acres,  $4,5.12. 

5.  This  calculation  is  usually  expressed  in  a  formula  as  fol- 
lows : 

mGc  — c(i.opin)-f- (Sc  +  E)  (i.op111— i>^(Ta(i.opm--a)+Tb  etc.) 

when  Ta  is  made  at  a  loss  or  is  a  negative  quantity,  —  Ta,  is  de- 
ducted from  costs  as  — ( — Ta)  as  in  the  sample  case  above. 

In  the  formula  ™Gc  means :  the  cost  value  of  one  acre  of  the 
growing  stock,  m  years  old. 

6.  The  above  case  fully  illustrates  the  usual  calculation.     If 
natural  reproduction  replaces  planting,  c  may  be  zero.     Similarly, 
if  there  are  expenses  of  clearing  the  land,  as  on  a  burn,  of  cultivat- 
ing the  plantation,   of  filling  fail  places,  etc.,  these  expenses  are 
charged  and  prolonged  exactly  as  planting,  c. 


EXPECTATION  VALUE  OF  STAND  63 

7.  In  the  above  case  the  cost  value  Sc  of  the  land  was  used. 
In  most  cases  it  is  but  natural  that  this  should  be  so.  But  where 
the  cost  value  is  practically  zero,  quite  common  where  the  land  and 
timber  were  bought  together  and  only  the  merchantable  timber  con- 
sidered in  the  price,  the  cost  value  is  misleading,  the  land  may  read- 
ily be  worth  five  or  ten  dollars  an  acre  and  so  have  an  accepted  sale 
value. 

In  such  cases  the  sale  value,  Ss,  is  used.  Occasionally  the  land 
has  neither  cost  nor  sale  value  which  could  be  agreed  upon,  for  in- 
stance, state  and  national  lands,  remote  mountain  or  non-agricultural 
land.  Here  the  temptation  is  to  ignore  the  value  of  the  land  entirely. 
This  is  wrong  since  any  land  which  can  and  does,  or  actually  has 
produced  a  crop  of  timber  having  value,  has  value  itself.  Incon- 
sistency here  is  liable  to  lead  to  trouble  for  sooner  or  later  the  value 
of  these  very  lands  may  come  in  question.  In  such  cases,  the  Se 
properly  based  and  discounted  should  be  substituted  as  S.  ~  /a^l 

To  employ  Se  without  deductions  is  hardly  advisable  since  Se 
is  rather  the  maximum  value  of  the  land  for  the  particular  purpose 
and  to  employ  a  maximum  price  in  these  calculations  is  hardly  safe 
or  satisfactory. 

c.     Expectation  value  of  growing  stock. 

Ordinary  case:  Spruce,  clear  cut,  and  plant;  rotation,  ninety 
years;  area,  eighty  acres;  age  of  stand,  forty-five  years,  p,  two  per 
cent. 

1.  Premises  per  acre: 

Land   value   Sc $20 

Yearly  current  expense  e 0.50 

Final  yield,  Yr,  stumpage  value,  40  M.  feet  at  $10  or. ...  400 

Thinning  at  50  years,  stumpage 30 

Thinning  at  70  years,  stumpage  , 60 

2.  Gross  income  per  acre  at  end  of  rotation : 

Final  yield '. $400 

Thinning  at  50  and  interest  for  40  years 66 

Thinning  at  70  and  interest  for  20  years   89 

Total     $555 

3.  Expenses  per  acre  to  end  of  rotation : 

Rent  of  land  and  current  expenses  treated  as  in  case  of  cost 
value, 

(SC  +  E)    (l.0pr-m-l)=r-  (20  +  25)    (I.0245— 1)....$64. 


64  FOREST  VALUATION 

4.  Net  income  per  acre  at  end  of  rotation  or  net  value  of  the 
stand  then,  $555  —  $64  or  $491. 

5.  Present  value  of  the  stand  on  basis  of  expected  income  : 
Final  value  discounted  to  date,  or 


I.02 

Value  of  the  stand  on  80  acres  —  $16.160. 

6.  This  calculation  may  be  put  in  a  general  formula  : 

mG    _YT-4-Ta(i.opr-a)4-Tb(i.opr-b)   etc.—  (Sc  +  E)  (i.opr-m—  i) 

i.opr-m 

where  mGe  means  the  expectation  value  of  one  acre  of  growing 
stock,  m  years  old. 

7.  It  is  evident  that  proper  allowances  must  be  made  in  esti- 
mating future  incomes,  i.e.,  that  these  values  must  be  reasonably 
conservative.     It  also  appears  that  if,  in  the  above  case,  $202  per 
acre  is  paid  and  the  values  are  secured  as  per  estimate,  the  buyer 
does  not  make  anything  over  and  above  his  two  per  cent  on  all  in- 
vestment.    Evidently  then,  the  full  expectation  value  is  the  maxi- 
mum which  can  be  paid  for  the  stand. 

Where  risks  of  injury  from  fire,  etc.,  are  great,  such  risks  are 
allowed  for  in  the  calculation  by  proper  deduction  from  the  values 
of  the  final  yield  and  thinnings. 

d.     Which  value  to  use. 

In  selling  and  buying  a  house  the  owner  first  considers  the  cost 
value  or  what  the  property  cost  him.  The  buyer  cares  little  or  noth- 
ing about  this  cost  value  but  considers  the  market  or  sale  value  or 
else  the  value  which  he  may  make  on  the  property.  So  in  the  valua- 
tion of  the  stand  of  timber.  The  buyer  does  not  care  whether  the 
cost  of  planting  was  high  or  low,  and  how  much  expense  the  owner 
had  in  care,  protection,  taxes,  etc.,  he  merely  cares  about  the  values 
which  he  can  make  out  of  the  timber,  the  sale  or  expectation  value. 

This  situation  is  complicated  by  the  uncertainties  of  a  living 
crop.  Commonly  the  age  and  condition  of  the  stand  decide.  If  a 
stand  of  pine  ten  years  old  is  injured  or  destroyed  the  question 
almost  naturally  is  —  what  did  it  cost  to  reproduce  or  grow  it,  what 
will  it  cost  to  replace  the  stand,  i.  e.,  what  is  the  cost  value? 

In  older  stands  it  is  the  sale  value  which  determines.  But  in 
many  cases,  especially  in  new  districts,  as  in  the  far  west,  it  often 
happens  that  even  a  fine,  mature  stand  of  timber  has  no  sale  value 


Otf  STOCK  IN  NORMAL,  FOREST  65 

at  all,  but  is  certain  to  have  a  value  as  soon  as  a  certain  railway  is 
finished.  Similarly  a  stand  of  lodge  pole  may  be  nearly  mature  and 
yet  be  a  few  inches  below  the  marketable  size ;  here  evidently  the 
stand  has  a  future  value  or  expectation  value,  though  neither  sale 
value  nor  an  accepted  cost  value  exist. 

In  the  courts  the  sale  value  has  always  been  accepted.  Of  late, 
since  these  matters  have  been  more  carefully  considered  and  the 
evidence  has  been  sufficient  and  clear,  both  cost  and  expectation 
value  have  been  admitted.  For  young  stands,  less  than  half  rota- 
tion, the  cost  value  or  cost  of  replacing  is  the  more  satisfactory. 

e.  Value  of  land  and  growing  stock,  together,  i,  e.,  value  of 
forest  with  even  age  stands. 

This  is  merely  a  matter  of  addition  of  the  values  of  land  and 
timber.  In  adding,  the  question  arises  as  to  the  use  of  cost,  sale  or 
expectation  value  of  both  land  and  timber.  As  stated  before,  this 
depends  on  the  viewpoint  of  the  person  making  the  valuation.  The 
owner  of  a  tract  of  timber  is  apt  to  use  cost  values  for  both  land 
and  timber,  the  buyer  will  use  sale  values  as  far  as  possible.  If  the 
stand  is  young,  he  too  is  apt  to  employ  cost  value  for  the  stand,  but 
is  quite  certain  to  use  the  sale  value  of  the  land,  for  it  would  be  use- 
less to  employ  cost  values  where  this  is  zero  or  at  least  uncertain. 
Both  buyer  and  seller  should  work  out  the  expectation  value  to  get 
a  fair  measure  and  check  on  all  sale  value  estimates.  Since  the 
growing  stock  is  expected  to  pay  rent  on  the  land,  the  value  of  the 
land  is  not  changed  by  the  fact  that  the  stand  must  remain  for  twen- 
ty or  more  years  on  the  land  before  removal  and  so  prevents  use  of 
the  land  for  other  purposes. 


G.  VALUE  OF  THE  GROWING  STOCK  OF  A  REGU- 
LATED OR  NORMAL  FOREST. 

When  the  State  of  Michigan  starts  out  to  establish  a  million 
acres  of  state  forest  it  must  determine:  how  much  capital  is  to  be 
tied  up  in  this  property  and  how  much  of  it  in  land  and  how  much 
in  perishable  growing  stock  or  trees  of  all  ages  from  the  seedling  to 
mature  timber.  The  same  is  true  of  any  owner  or  buyer  who  con- 
siders selling,  buying  or  developing  a  real  forest  business.  The  im- 
portance of  the  growing  stock  in  such  a  business  is  great  since  it 
usually  makes  from  sixty  to  eighty  per  cent  of  the  entire  value  of 
the  property. 


66  FORF,ST  VALUATION 

a.     The  regulated  or  normal  forest. 

1.  Premises:    Area,  16,000  acres. 

Method,  clear  cut,  and  plant,  even  age  stands. 
Rotation,  80  years. 

Thinnings  every  10  years,  beginning  when  the  stand  is  ten  years 
old,  the  last  at  seventy  years. 

2.  Condition  of  forest  in  spring  just  after  planting: 
Two  hundred  acres  just  planted,  growing  stock  o  years  old. 
Two  hundred  acres  growing  stock  I  year  old,  etc. 

Two  hundred  acres  79  years  old,  or  r-i  years  old. 

3.  Yearly  work,  expense  and  income  on  this  forest: 
Two  hundred  acres  are  cut.  income  200  x  Yr. 

Fourteen  hundred  acres  thinned,  income  T10  (200),  T20  (200), 
T30  (200),  etc. 

Two  hundred  acres  are  planted,  200  x  c. 

Sixteen  thousand  acres  protected  and  cared  for  in  road  building 
and  other  improvements,  taxes  paid,  cost  16,000  x  e. 

Sixteen  thousand  acres  growing  stock  pay  rent  of  land  16,000 
x  Sc  (.op). 

4.  A  proper  sample  of  this  regulated  forest  would  contain  80 
acres,  one  acre  just  planted,  one  acre  with  one  year  old  stuff,  one 
acre  two  years  old,  etc.  to  one  acre  79  years  old,  taken  from  the 
oldest  stands.     Whatever  is  true  as  to  the  average  value  of  this 
sample  of  eighty  acres  applies  to  the  whole  forest  of  16,000  acres 
so  that  if  the  growing  stock  on  the  sample  eighty  acres  is  worth 
fifty  dolars  an  acre  on  the  average,  the  growing  stock  on  the  16,000 
is  worth  fifty  dollars  an  acre  average. 

b.  Expectation  value  of  the  growing  stock  of  the  regulated 
or  normal  forest. 

For  sake  of  simplicity  the  rotation  is  assumed  to  be  only  ten 
years  so  that  the  sample  of  the  regulated  forest  contains  ten  acres. 
Diagram,  Fig.  I,  illustrates  this  lo-acre  sample  and  indicates  the 
present  value  of  yields,  Yr,  and  thinnings,  which  are  to  be  obtained. 

The  yearly  work  and  expense  and  income  on  this  lo-acre  sam- 
ple are: 

One  acre  cut,  income  Yr. 

One  acre  thinned,  when  stand  is  4  years  old,  income  T4. 

One  acre  planted,  costs  c. 

Ten  acres  protected,  cared  for,  taxes  paid,  expenses  10  x  e. 
Ten  acres  of  growing  stock  pay  rent  on  the  10  acres  of  land,  cost 
ipXSc(.op). 


IN  NORMAI, 


67 


2.  Adding  the  values  of  the  growing  stock  of  the  10  acres 
gives  the  value  of  the  growing  stock  for  the  entire  sample  of  10 
acres  and  dividing  this  sum  gives  the  average  value  per  acre  for  the 
sample,  and  also  of  the  regulated  forest. 


T-\ 

Jalue 


dalive    o^ 
oxve       o. 


H 


\  \\ 


T-5 


\x\xv\\\as  ex 


T-b 


0- 


0 


T-l 


X-8 


T-\0 


\.op'° 


Fig.  i.  Diagram  representing  10  acres  (r  acres),  a  sample  of  a  forest  regulated  on  a 
year  rotation,  indicating  the  age  of  the  growing  stock  on  each  acre;  the  present  value  of 
e  final  yield  (Fr)  from  each,  and  the  present  value  of  the  thinnings  expected  from  each 
.re.  Since  Yr  on  the  acre  of  7  year  old  stuff  is  to  be  cut  in  3  years,  its  final  value,  or 
umpage  value  is  discounted  for  3  years.  On  the  several  acres  4,  or  more  years  old,  no 
rther  thinning  is  to  be  expecte^,  but  the  stand  3  years  old  will  furnish  a  thinning  next 
jar,  and  hence  the  value  of  this  is  discounted  for  one  year,  etc. 


Since  the  general  formula  for  expectation  value  of  growing 
stock  reads: 

mGe  =   Yr  +  Ta(i.opr-a)  — (Sc  -I-  E)  (i.opr-m— i) 
i.opr-m 

the  value  of  the  several  acres  beginning  with  the  oldest  stand  may 
be  written : 

op    _Yr-f  o— (Sc  +  E)  (i.opr-9—  i) 


°Ge=: 


i.opr 


NOTE: — The   thinning   from   this   acre   has   been   taken  •and   no.   further 
thinning  is  expected. 


68  FOREST  VALUATION 

«Ge  =  Yr-f-o  —  (Sc-f  E)  (i.opr-8-i) 

* 

sOe  __  Yr  +  T4(i.op'--4)  —  (Sc  4-  E)  (i.opr-3—  i  » 
i.  op1"-3 


and  °Ge  = 


Yr  +  T4(l-°Pr~4)—  (S'C  4-  E)  (i.opr-°—  i)* 


To  get  a  common  denominator  for  S  Ta,  treat  in  this  manner  : 

Ta(l.0pa—  i)  I.ppr-a     __  Ta(l.Opr-a)   (i.ppa—  .T) 

I0pa(i.op—  I       v     I.Opr-a    '  I.0pr(l.0p—  I 

adding  we  have  : 


q.(r-i?C  (Yr  +  E  +  Sc)   (l.Opr—  l)+Ta(l.Opr-a)    (i.opa-i)  _  ( 

(I.0pr)   (l.Op—  I) 

as  the  expectation  value  of  the  growing  stock  on  the  ten-acre,  or  r 
acre  sample.  Dividing  this  by  r  the  average  value  of  the  growing 
stock  per  acre  is  obtained  and  the  formula  reads: 

°-(r-1)Ge  average  per  acre  = 

(Yr  +  E+Sc)    (l.0pr—  -  1)+  Ta(l.opr-a)   (l.ppa—  i] 

r(i.opr)  (i.op-i) 

3.  To  illustrate:  Assume  an  area  16,000;  clear  cut,  and  plant, 
P,  2%. 

Rotation,  80  years. 

Premises  per  acre  :  final  yield  or  Yr,  stumpage  value  per  acre, 
$400. 

Thinning  at  20  years,  no  income. 

Thinning  at  40  years,  $10  stumpage. 

Thinning  at  60  years,  $20  stumpage.  • 

1.50 

Current  expenses  $1.50,  hence  E  =  --  ,  or  $75.   • 

.02 

Cost  value  of  land,  Sc,  $10. 


*For  the  class  it  is  helpful  to  write  these  out  as  follows: 

Yr  Ta(i.opr-a)  _  QSc  4-  E) i.opr-m 

~  i.opr-m  i.opr-m  i.opr-m  i.ppr 

this  makes  addition  of  SYr,  2Ta,  etc.,  much  easier  and  clearer. 


THE  SIMPLE:  FORMULA  69 

The  average  value  per  acre  of  the  growing  stock  on  this  forest 


is: 


(400  +  75  +  10)    (1.02s0— I ) +10(1.02**)    (l.024°—  l)+20(l.02a>)    (I.0260— I) 

80(I.02S°)    (1.02— I) 

-(75+io) 
—  253  —  85  =  $168  per  acre,  or  about  $2,688,000  for  the  property. 

This  case  closely  resembles  a  fair  case  in  spruce  in  Germany, 
site  II,  except  that  the  cost  value  of  the  land  is  taken  rather  low. 
The  calculation  indicates  that  the  growth  produced  by  this  growing 
stock  will  pay  two  per  cent  on  the  capital  invested  in  the  property 
and  composed  of  $160,000  for  land  and  $2,688,000  in  growing  stock. 

4.  Simplifying  the  above  formula  by  substituting  Se,  or  its 
value  for  Sc,  results  as  follows  and  gives  a  very  useful  form: 


sinceSe  =  Yr  +  Ta(i.opr-a)—  c(  i.opr)—  £(  i.opr—  i) 
(i.opi— i) 

Se  (i.opr — i)   may  replace  Sc  (i.opr — i)   in  the  above  for- 
mula as  follows : 


--e  per  acre  = 
Yr(i.opr—  i)4-E(i.opr—  i).f  Yr  +  Ta(i.opr-a)—  c(i.opr)—  E(i.opr— 


r(  i.opi-)  (i.op—  i) 

)   Ci.0pa—  i) 


T(l.Opr)   (I.op-l) 

which  simplifies  into  : 


,p 


Yr  +  Ta—  c  Yr  +  Ta  —  c  —  re 

E--Se  -Se 


In  this  last  form  the  formula  clearly  shows  the  work,  expense 
and  income  of  the  r  acre  sample,  of  the  regulated  forest.  The  yearly 
income  is  Yr  and  Ta;  the  yearly  expenses  are  c  and  re,  the  differ- 
ence is  the  net  income  from  the  r  acres.  This  net  income  divided  by 
r  is  the  net  income  per  acre,  and  this  capitalized  gives  the  income 
value  of  the  forest,  i.  e.,  land  and  timber  together,  so  that  the  value 
of  the  growing  stock  is  this  income  value  of  property  minus  the 
value  of  the  land. 

Using  the  premises  set  before  and  putting  c  =  $io  and  replac- 
ing Sc  with  Se  at  $28  we  have  : 

400  +10  4-  20  —TO  —120  Q        ^ 

Value  of  growing  stock  per  acre—       —  g,  Q^  —  —20  =  ^159. 

In  this  particular  case  the  result,  $159,  compares  closely  enough 
with  $  1  68  as  obtained  by  the  ordinary  formula.  In  any  case  it  is 


70  FOREST  VALUATION 

necessary  to  keep  in  mind  that  this  simple  formula  depends  on  sub- 
stituting Se  for  other  values  of  soil,  Sc  or  Ss. 

c.     Cost  value  of  the  growing  stock  of  a  regulated  forest. 

In  this  case  the  value  of  the  growing  stock  of  the  ten-acre  sam- 
ple is  obtained  by  adding  the  values  of  the  ten  acres,  writing  the 
value  of  each  by  the  general  formula  as  developed  before  : 

mGc  —  c(i.opm)  +  (E  +  Sc)  (i.op171—  i)—  Ta(i.opm-a) 


where  again  m  is  the  age  of  any  one  stand. 
i.     This  leads  to  the  formula: 


per  acre= 


2.  To  illustrate:    forest  of  16,000  acres,  clear  cut,  and  plant; 
rotation,  80  years  ;  p,  2%  ;  premises  per  acre  : 

Cost  value  of  land,  $10. 
Cost  of  planting,  $10. 
Current  expense,  $1.50,  hence  E,  $75. 
Thinning  at  20  years,  no  income. 
Thinning  at  40  years,  $10. 
Thinning  at  60  years,  $20. 
Then  the  average  cost  value  of  growing  stock  per  acre  : 

(10  +  7=;  +  10)    (l.02S°  —  i)  —  IO(I.024°  —  l)  —  •2O(l.O22°  —  i)         , 

80(1.02-1)  -(75  +  io)=  $131 

and  for  16,000  acres  about  $2,096,000. 

3.  Simplification  of  this  formula  by  substituting  Se(i.opr  —  i) 
for  Sc(i.opr  —  i)  results  in  the  same  form  found  for  Q-^-^Ge  so 
that: 


when  Se  is  employed  as  the  value  of  the  land  in  place  of  Sc,  or  Ss. 


H.     VALUE  OF  THE  GROWING  STOCK  IN  THE  ALL- 
AGED  OR  MANY-AGED  FOREST. 

Two  cases  arise :  the  regulated  and  the  irregular  forest. 

a.  The  stand  is  truly  all-aged  and  regular  as  in  the  case  of  a 
well  managed  selection  forest.  Here  old  and  young  are  in  proper 
proportion,  all  age  classes  are  represented  and  occupy  equal  areas. 
The  difference  between  the  growing  stock  of  this  forest  and  that 
of  a  forest  of  even  aged  stands  is  merely  in  the  distribution  of  old 


Y-\IYUE  OI-   ALL-AGED  STAND  7 1 

and  young  on  the  ground.  Theoretically  at  least,  the  following 
holds :  if  the  rotation  is  120  years,  the  area  3,600  acres,  the  period 
of  return  20  years,  so  that  each  year  180  acres  are  cut  over,  each 

rotation 

one  of  the  180  acre  lots  contains  six  age  classes,  -  — ,  and  on 

return 

the  3,600  acres  all  age  classes,  from  I — 120  year  old  stuff,  are  repre- 
sented, provided  reproduction  is  secured  promptly,  as  is  here  as- 
sumed. On  each  i8o-acre  lot  the  trees  of  the  six  age  classes  would 
occupy  the  same  amount  of  ground,  30  acres,  not  in  separated  areas, 
but  mixed,  so  that  every  acre  would  have  old.  young  and  middle  aged 
stuff,  i.  e.,  trees  of  all  six  age  classes.  If  this  forest  were  cut  over 
every  ten  years,  each  lot  would  have  twelve  age  classes,  and  if  cut 
over  every  year  every  lot  should  contain  every  age  class  from  one 
to  one  hundred  and  twenty  years  old. 

The  work,  expenses  and  income  from  this  regulated  forest  of 
many-aged  stands  would  be  similar  to  that  on  the  regulated  forest 
of  even  aged  stands.  Every  year  there  is : 

a.  A  cut  of  180  acres,  (but  not  clear  cut),  which  takes: 

1.  The  mature,  I2o-year-old  stuff,  theoretically  occupying  30 
acres,  but  scattered  all  over  the  180  acres. 

2.  Thinnings,  and  stuff  cut  to  improve  the  woods  on  the  180 
acres,  really  from  150  acres. 

b.  The  entire  3,600  acres  are  protected  and  cared  for  in  im- 
provements, etc.,  and  have  taxes  paid  on  them. 

c.  The  growing  stock  must  pay  rent  on  the  3,600  acres  of  land. 
To  illustrate  the  computation:    The  yearly  income  is  the  stuff 

cut  from  the  180  acres,  or  30  Yr  +150  acres  thinnings,  say,  $10,000; 
the  expenses  $5,500  per  year;  net  income  $4,500  per  year;  cap- 
italizing this  at  3%  gives  the  forest  an  income  value  or  expectation 

4500 
value  of  -    —  or  $150,000  for  land  and  timber  together. 

•03 

To  find  the  value  of  the  growing  stock  on  this  forest  the  value 
of  the  land  is  deducted.  This  value  of  the  land  may  be  cost  value 
or  sale  value  or  expectation  value,  according  to  the  object  of  the  cal- 
culation or  viewpoint  of  the  person  making  this  valuation.  If  the 
land  cost  $10  per  acre  and  this  value  appears  satisfactory  to  use, 
the  growing  stock  on  this  forest  is  worth  $114,000,  or  about  $31.60 
per  acre,  on  the  basis  of  the  yearly  income  it  can  produce  and  is  ex- 
pected to  produce. 


72  FOREST  VALUATION 

b.  The  irregular  forest  of  many-aged  stands  requires  a  val- 
uation from  stand  to  stand  and  no  general  calculation  can  apply. 
Such  a  forest  can  not  possibly  yield  a  uniform  income,  steadily  until 
it  is  changed  by  systematic, regulation.  In  our  wild  woods  the  fol- 
lowing three  forms  or  conditions  are  common : 

1.  The  stand  is  generally  mature,   the  merchantable  timber 
makes  up  seventy-five  per  cent  and  more  of  all  growing  stock.   Such 
stands  have  little  value  beyond  that  of  the  merchantable  timber,  for 
usually  the  rest  is  stunted  and  is  injured  during  the  removal  of  the 
old  stuff.    This,  then,  is  a  case  of  stumpage  values. 

2.  The  stand  is  largely  middle  age  stuff,  which  may  be  ex- 
pected to  be  merchantable  in  a  certain  number  of  years,  as  seen  by 
growth  studies.     Here  it  is  simply  a  case  of  mGe,  as  developed 
before. 

3.  The  stand  is  mostly  young  stuff,  such  as  reproduction  on 
burns,  windfall,  etc.   In  these  cases  the  cost  value,  mGc,  should  pre- 
vail.   Where  such  reproduction  comes  in  with  open,  mature,  or  over 
mature  stands,  the  area  of  the  young  stand  is  estimated;  its  cost 
value  and  the  stumpage  value  of  the  old  stuff  are  determined  sep- 
arately. 


IV.    RELATION  OF  CAPITAL  AND 
INCOME  IN  FORESTRY 

A.     NATURE  OF  INCOME  AND  PROFIT  IN  FORESTRY. 

i.     General  notion  of  profit. 

a.  If  an  article  for  a  store  is  bought  at  one  dollar  and  sold  at  a 
dollar  and  a  quarter  there  is  twenty-five  cents  profit,  or  the  profit  is 

25%. 

b.  If  a  house,  bought  at  $1,000,  is  sold  within  two  months  at 
$1,200,  the  profit  is  $200,  or  20%. 

c.  An  office  building  in  a  small  town  cost  $150,000,  there  is 
little  demand  for  this  and  the  income  after  paying  taxes,  running 
expenses  and  upkeep  is  about  $3,000  per  year.    There  is  this  net  in- 
come but  no  one  considers  the  building  a  profitable  one.     To  the 
contrary  it  is  well  known  as  a  "losing  proposition."    Savings  banks 
and  the  best  commercial  papers  would  pay  twice  this  income.     In 
figuring  the  loss  it  is  asumed  that  the  capital  of  $150,000  should 
have  been  invested  at  4%,  the  income  therfore,  $6,000,  that  the 
yearly  loss  is  $3,000,, or  2%  on  the  money;  and  if  the  building  had 
to  be  sold  this  would  mean  a  total  loss  of  $75,000.    We  have  income 
here  but  certainly  no  profit. 

d.  A  house  is  bought  at  $i>ooo  and  current  rate  of  interest 
is  5%,  the  true  net  income  from  this  house  is  $80  per  year.    Evident- 
ly the  new  owner  makes  8%  on  his  money  and  the  house  nets  him 
3%  more  than  the  current  interest  rate.     In  this  case  there  is  a 
profit,  even  though  the  owner  does  not  sell,  and  this  profit  is  3%  and 
not  8%.     In  this  way  the  net  income  from  the  house  divides  itself 
into  two  parts,  a  reasonable  regular  income  on  the  capital  invested, 
i.  e.,  the  5%  on  the  $1,000,  and  a  3%  profit. 

Since  on  this  point  authors  vary,  some  putting  the  net  income 
as  synonymous  or  at  least  interchangeable  with  profit,  the  position 
taken  in  these  discussions  is  here  stated. 

e.  A  farm  is  bought  at  $5,000,  the  new  owner  borrows  $2,000 
additional  at  5%  as  a  working  capital  to  buy  teams,  tools,  etc.    He 
produces  a  net  income  of  $700  or  10%  on  all  the  money  put  into  the 
enterprise.     He  pays  his  creditor  $100  yearly  interest  and  retains 
$600.    This  $600  makes  12%  on  the  farmer's  own  money  so  that  he 
has  his  regular  5%  income  and  7%  profit  in  this  business.    But  even 


74  FOREST  VALUATION 

here  there  is  a  doubt  as  to  whether  part  of  this  seven  per  cent  profit 
is  not  a  personal  matter. 

These  few  cases  suffice  to  show  that  the  matter  of  profit  is  not 
as  simple  as  it  seems ;  a  great  variety  of  combinations  necessarily 
arise,  there  may  be  profit  even  though  there  is  no  sale  of  property, 
and  also  there  are  various  viewpoints  possible. 

f .  A  man  buys  a  house  for  $5,000,  he  borrows  the  entire  sum, 
giving  the  house  as  security.  In  one  month  he  sells  the  house  at 
$7,500,  and  returns  teh  cash  with  a  few  dollars  interest.  The  profit 
is  practically  $2,500  and  is  not  made  on  any  real  investment  on  his 
part.  It  is  usually  stated  that  his  credit  is  used,  etc.,  but  in  many 
cases  this  is  not  true  at  all ;  the  capitalist  does  not  trust  the  man  but 
considers  the  house  good  for  the  money. 

It  is  neither  ordinary  profit  nor  wages  but  a  special  form  of 
profit  paying  him  for  his  enterprise,  shrewdness  or  more  often  his 
good  luck,  exactly  as  in  gambling. 

2.     Profit  from  income  producing  properties. 

a.  In  case  under  i,  c,  a  house  is  bought  at  $1,000,  the  interest 
rate  is  5%,  the  net  income  $80  or  8%  on  the  money  invested,  the 
yearly  profit  is  $30  or  3%.  The  cost  value  of  the  house,  He  is  $1,000, 

80 

income  value  He  is  -    -  or  $1,600,  the  total  profit  is  $1,600  —  $1,000 
•05 

or  $600  and  may  be  stated  as  He  —  He. 

b.  A  forest  property  is  bought  at  $250,000,  it  produces  $10,000 
per  year  or  4%  on  the  investment,  net  income.    Whether  this  would 
be  regarded  a  profitable  investment  or  not  depends  on  the  purchaser, 
chances  for  investment,  the  current  rate  of  interest,  etc.     In  central 
Europe  it  would  be  considered  an  excellent  property,  in  the  United 
States  at  present,  it  would  be  considered  poor,  in  the  west,  barely 
paying  in  the  middle  states,  fair  in  the  east.     Any  one  who  could 
easily  get  five  per  cent  on  his  money  would  not  buy  this  property, 
and  would  certainly  not  speak  of  a  profit  in  this  case. 

Assume  now  that  the  property  yields  $20,000  per  year  or  8%, 
then  the  case  is  similar  to  that  of  the  house,  i.  e., 
Cost  value  of  forest,  $250,000. 

20,000 

Income  value or  400,000. 

•05 


WHAT   IS  PROFIT  75 

The  yearly  profit  is  $20,000  —  $12,500  or  $7,500,  or  expressed 
in  per  cent  it  is  8%  —  5%  or  3%  ;  and  expressed  as  a  total  it  is 
$400,000  —  $250,000  or  $150.000  which  may  be  stated  as: 

profit  =  Fe  —  Fc. 

That  the  same  reasoning  applies  to  land  which  is  to  be  used  for 
forest  is  evident  and  leads  to  the  statement :  Profit  =  Se  —  Sc. 

3.     Profit  from  a  forest  not  producing  regular  yearly  income. 

Usual  case:  A  tract  of  40  acres  of  timber  is  bought  at  $5,000,  the 
owner  is  not  ready  to  cut  the  timber,  it  is  not  to  be  sold,  or  else  no 
offer  is  made ;  in  many  cases  of  this  kind  in  the  more  remote  districts, 
it  might  be  impossible  at  times  to  get  a  buyer  even  at  half  the  real 
value  of  the  timber;  there  is  neither  loss  nor  profit  here  actually  es- 
tablished until  the  timber  is  cut  or  some  sale  is  made.  As  a  fore- 
cast, however,  it  may  be  possible  and  worth  while  to  work  out  an 
expectation  value  in  the  manner  outlined  before,  and  then  the  prob- 
able or  expected  profit  is  equal  to  the  expectation  value  of  this  40 
acres  minus  the  cost  value,  in  this  case  $5,000. 

From  the  foregoing  illustration,  it  is  evident  that  the  term  profit 
is  clear  and  that  it  is  consistently  employed  in  the  ordinary  store,  and 
in  ordinary  sale  of  property.  But  when  employed  in  connection 
with  the  regular  income  from  a  house,  farm  or  forest,  factory,  etc., 
it  is  not  clear,  being  confused,  commonly,  with  gross,  or  net  incomes 
and  largely  loses  its  usefulness. 


B.     INTEREST  MADE  BY  THE  FOREST. 

In  forestry  the  question  frequently  comes  up — what  rate  of  in- 
terest is  made  by  the  growth  of  timber  on  a  given  tract.  Three 
cases  may  be  distinguished : 

a.  The  growth  of  a  single  stand  such  as  a  4O-acre  stand  of 
even  aged  timber. 

b.  The  growth  of  a  regulated  forest,  or  more  precisely,  of  a 
working  section  with  perfect  age  class  conditions. 

c.  The  growth  of  timber  which  may  be  produced  on  an  area 
of  land  which  is  bare  to  start  with. 

i.     The  interest  made  by  a  single  even  aged  stand  of  timber. 

Here  the  usual  case  considers  the  growth  for  only  a  short  period, 
say  10  years,  but  frequently,  however,  it  demands  the  interest  made 
by  the  growth  for  an  entire  rotation. 


76  FOREST  VALUATION 

a.  Interest  made  by  the  growth  of  a  stand  during  a  short 
period  or  part  of  a  rotation:  If  the  cost  value  of  the  land  is  $10 
per  acre  and  the  cost  value  of  the  stand,  now  30  years  old,  is  $80, 
then  the  amount  invested  in  this  enterprise  is  $90  per  acre.  Evi- 
dently the  only  increase  in  value  of  this  piece  of  forest  is  due  to  the 
growth  of  the  timber.  If  the  growth  in  volume,  quality  and  mar- 
ket price  amounts  to  $20  in  5  years  then  this  $20  represents  the  in- 
terest for  5  years  on  the  $90  invested,  and  approximately  the  rate  of 


20  X 

interest  is:  —          —or  4.4%.     While  this  calculation  is  a  fair  ap- 
5X90 

proximation  it  requires  modification  for  larger  enterprises,  and  bet- 
ter analysis.  The  following  illustrates  the  usual  modification. 

Area,  40  acres  ;  stand,  even  aged  50  years  old  at  beginning  of 
period,  and  55  at  end;  p,  2%  ;  land,  $10  per  acre;  yearly  expenses, 

e 

e,  $i  per  acre;  therfore  —  -  or  E  is  $50;  the  value  of  the  stand  at 

.02 

Cn 
50  years  is  $250  and  at  55  is  $300.  The  reasoning  then  is  :  i.opn  =  —  . 

Co 

The  initial  capital,  Co,  is  made  up  of  stand  at  50  years,  land,  and  E, 
the  final  capital,  Cn,  of  stand  at  55,  plus  land  and  E,  and  we  may 
set: 

Y53  4-  S  -f  E       $300  4-io  4-  50 

i.  op  =          '  =   ^  -  •  -  f-*-     —  1.16  and  hence  p  =  3%. 

Y°°  4-  S  -j-  E        $250  -f  10  4-  50 

This  per  cent  made  by  the  current  growth  of  the  stand  may  be  term- 
ed "forest  per  cent,"  or  Pf,  and  is  the  "Weiser"  per  cent  of  the  Ger- 
man authors. 

The  formula  as  written  bv  Endres  is  : 


w 


AH-B4-V 
or  in  our  terms, 


/„  lYx+n  4-  S  -I-  E 

"  =  ""(>/ Y.  +  SI-E  - 


which  readily  changes  into  the  above  simple  form. 

This  form  of  analysis  was  used  by  Pressler  and  Heyer  over 
fifty  years  ago.  It  is  useful  in  determinig  whether  a  given  stand 
should  be  cut  or  left  standing,  the  usual  assumption  is  that  if  the 


FOREST  PER  CENT  77 

per  cent  drops  below  3%  or  whatever  per  cent  may  reasonably  be 
demanded  by  the  owner,  the  stand  is  no  longer  worth  holding. 

While  the  calculation  is  quite  simple  the  actual  determination 
in  the  woods  is  not  easy  and  is  never  more  than  an  estimate  rein- 
forced by  measuring  the  outer  rings  of  a  few  trees. 

From  these  measurements  the  Pv  or  growth  in  volume  in  per 
cent  is  determined  by  Schneider's  formula;  the  per  cent  growth  in 
quality  is  estimated  on  a  basis  of  diameter  at  beginning  and  end  of 
the  period,  and  the  per  cent  increase  in  market  price  is  a  figure 
worked  out  for  several  years  in  any  given  district.  Having  this,  the 
growth  of  the  stand  is  expressed  in  per  cent  for  the  three  lines  and 
Pressler  conceived  the  idea  of  simply  using  these  as  follows :  assum- 

Ym 
ing  the  actual  growth  in  value  per  year  is :  (Pv  +  Pq  +  Ps) 

and  that  this  growth  is  made  on  a  capital  Ym  -f-  Se. 


100 


Then  pf  =  (pv  -f-  pq  ~j-ps)  IOQ  (Ym+  Se)    =  ^pv  ~^  P<1  ~'r  ps^    Ym  -Tse 

To  illustrate :   If  the  stand  is  worth  $250  and  land  $10  per  acre 
and 


pv=i.; 
pq=I 

ps— I 


or  3-'i%. 


Since  this  method  or  inquiry  is  usually  applied  only  to  older 
stands  where  the  value  of  the  timber  is  very  large  as  compared  with 

Ym 

the  value  of  the  land,  the  value  of may  be  put  =  I  and  for 

Ym  +  Se 

ordinary  purposes,  therf ore,  it  is  quite  sufficient  to  state : 

Pf  =  Pv  +  Pq  +  Ps ;  in  the  above  case  pf  =  1.3  +  I  +  I  =  3.3%,  a 

very  convenient  form. 

In  the  United  States  where  at  present  the  value  of  timber  is 
usually  by  M.  ft.  b.m.  on  rather  uniform  price  per  M.  feet,  the  case 
of  working  out  the  data  for  pf  may  take  the  following  form : 

Assume  stand  of  pine,  pure,  even  aged,  80  years  old;  volume 
table  exists  for  species  and  district ;  from  borings  or  felling  the 
diameter  growth  of  the  timber  is  ascertained,  the  stand  is  calipered 


7  8  FOREST  VALUATION 

and  volume  known  ;  stumpage  $10  per  M.  feet  ;  assume  that  the  stand 
now,  80  years  old,  contains  250  M.  feet.  Value  of  this  250  X  10  = 
$2,500. 

From  growth  study  it  appears  that  the  stand  10  years  ago  con- 
tained 200  M.  feet,  valued  at  $2,000.  Then  the  growth  in  value,  be- 
side increase  in  market  price,  is  $500  in  10  years.  Expressed  as  per 
cent: 


I.OPx10=   —  =  1.25  Px=  2.3%. 

This  px  or  2.3%  includes  both  the  growth  in  volume  and  the 
growth  in  quality  as  it  finds  expression  in  our  present  day  practice 
of  scaling  timber  so  that  we  may  state:  2.3%  —  px  =  Pv  +  pq,  and 
this  requires  merely  the  addition  of  ps  or  the  growth  in  market  price 
to  state  the  total  growth  in  value. 

b.  Rate  of  interest  made  by  the  growth  of  an  even  aged  stand 
during  the  entire  rotation,  i.  e.,  from  the  time  of  planting  to  time 
of  cutting. 

Here  again  it  is  convenient  to  apply  the  fundamental  form  of 
reasoning  that 

r Cr  Capital  or  values  at  end  of  rotation 

Co  ~~       Capital  or  values  at  'beginning 

The  initial  capital  Co  is  made  up  of :  land,  Sc ;  cost  of  planting,  c, 
or  the  value  of  young  growth ;  capital  E,  to  take  care  of  the  stand, 
pay  taxes,  protection,  etc. 

While  this  capital,  E,  is  not  really  on  hand,  the  results  are  the 
same,  the  owner  must  provide  from  some  source,  an  amount  equal 
to  the  interest  on  E  at  p  per  cent.  At  the  end,  or  time  of  cutting 
the  final  capital,  Cr,  into  which  Co  has  grown,  is  made  up  of :  land, 
Sc;  capital  for  expenses,  E,  stand  of  ripe  timber,  Yr,  and  the  state- 
ment becomes : 

r_  stand  +  land  +  expense  capital  _  Yr  +  Sc  +  E 

~  land  +  expense  capital  +  cost  of  planting         c  +  Sc  +  E 

Concrete  case:    Land  $15  per  acre,  p  — 2%,  e  =  $i,  hence  E 

I.  00 

_  =  $50 ;  Yr,  $400 ;  c,  $12  ;  r,  80  years ;  then : 

465       ,. 

=  TT  =  6.04 


12  +  15  +  50         77 
and  from  tables  :  pf  =  2.3%. 


FOREST  PER  CENT  79 

The  above  formula  may  also  be  written : 


p=  ic 

which  is  nothing  more  than  the  old  form  of  the  Weiser  per  cent, 
where  the  period  includes  the  entire  rotation,  c  the  cost  of  planting 
represents  the  value  of  the  stand  just  planted  or  at  the  beginning, 
and  Yr  is  the  value  of  the  stand  at  the  end  of  the  period. 

Whether  the  value  of  the  land  is  taken  at  cost,  sale  or  expecta- 
tion value  is  optional.  Certainly  the  introduction  of  Se  means  the 
use  of  a  maximum  which  is  not  to  be  recommended.  Since  the  val- 
ues of  land  are  apt  to  change  very  decidedly  during  a  period  of 
eighty  years  it  is  not  only  permissible  but  even  proper  to  set  a  higher 
value  for  S  in  the  numerator,  i.  e.,  in  the  final  capital,  than  in  the 
denominator  or  initial  capital. 

In  some  recent  publications  the  formula  is  written  in  a  modified 
form  as : 

Yr  4-  S  —  Ex  i.opr— T 

i.opr=  0    ,    „ —  and  Ei  is  equivalent  to  e 

I. op— i 

or  merely  the  end  value  of  all  expenses  during  this  one  rotation  com- 
pounded at  ordinary  interest  rate,  the  assumption  being  that  money 
is  borrowed  (actually  or  not)  at  ordinary  rates  for  this  purpose  of 
paying  taxes,  protection,  etc.  It  is  evident  that  this,  as  well  as  many 
other  forms,  is  possible  and  that  some  uniformity  in  the  use  of  the 
letters  and  writing  of  these  formulae  will  greatly  help  all  concerned. 
Where  thinnings  are  made,  and  this  must  be  assumed  as  the 
normal  condition  in  forestry,  the  above  formula  is  incomplete  and 
must  be  modified  to  take  care  of  the  receipts  from  thinnings.  This 
may  be  done  as  follows : 


2.  Rate  of  interest  made  by  a  regulated  forest,  or  one  pro- 
ducing a  regular  yearly  income. 

Since  the  yearly  net  income  is  in  the  nature  of  interest  on  the 
capital  invested  in  the  forest  and  since  this  income  is  known,  it  is 
necessary  only  to  determine  the  value  of  the  property,  stand,  and 
land.  But  as  this  may  be  cost,  sale,  or  expectation  value  of  either 
land  or  stand,  a  variety  of  conditions  are  possible. 

Where  the  forest  has  been  purchased  in  recent  time,  where  the 
income  so  far  received  has  paid  all  expenses  including  an  acceptable 
rate  of  interest,  and  where  the  management  has  prevented  any  de- 


80  FOREST  VALUATION 

terioration  of  the  forest,  the  cost  price  is  evidently  the  capital  in 
vested,  and  the  rate  of  interest  made  by  this  forest  is  : 

yearly  net  income 

X  loo 


, 
co&t  value  of  forest 

If  the  man  bought  the  forest  at  $250,000  and  receives  $10,000  per 
year  net  income,  he  evidently  makes  4%. 

If  this  same  man  paid  $250,000  ten  years  ago  and  has  "put 
back"  $50,000  to  develop  a  better  road  system  then  evidently  the  for- 
est costs  him  more  nearly  $300.000  and  the  $10,000  income  is  about 
3%  on  the  cost  value  of  the  property.  Similarly,  if  instead  of  get- 
ting $10,000  net  income  he  has  saved  with  a  view  to  improving  the 
growing  stock  on  the  property  and  has  secured  only  $5,000  per  year 
net  income,  the  $5,000  reduction  of  cut  is  an  investment  and  in- 
creases the  cost  value. 

Again,  the  forest  may  be  part  of  an  old  estate  or  it  may  have 
been  bought  twenty  years  ago  at  a  "bargain"  so  that  the  present 
cost  value  is  not  clear  and  certainly  not  equal  to  the  present  sale 
value  of  the  property.  In  this  case  the  income  is  not  referred  to  the 
cost  value  but  to  the  sale  value. 

With  properties  which  are  not  common  objects  of  sale  like  state 
forests,  national  forests,  etc.,  the  value  of  the  property  itself  is 
based  on  the  very  income  made  from  it  together  with  an  assumed 
interest  rate.  The  forest  producing  $10,000  per  year  net  income 
would  be  valued  by  capitalizing  the  $10,000  at,  say,  3%,  and  the 

10,000 

capital  value  would  be  ---  or  $333,000. 

-03 

If  this  capitalization  is  now  accepted  it  may  serve  as  a  measure 
to  find  the  forest  per  cent  for  future  years.  For  the  present,  how- 
ever, this  value  of  the  forest  must  be  regarded  as  arbitrary,  for  it 
would  have  been  just  as  fair  to  use  two  or  four  as  the  per  cent  of 
capitalization,  and  for  the  present,  therefore,  the  per  cent  or  interest 
rate  which  this  forest  makes  can  not  be  determined  for  lack  of  ac- 
ceptable basis,  the  value  of  the  property  on  which  the  $10,000  were 
made. 

In  determining  the  rate  of  interest  made  by  any  property  pro- 
ducing regular  yearly  income  there  enters  the  notion  or  custom  of 
"watering  stock."  In  the  above  case,  for  instance,  the  owner  would 
at  once  set  a  much  higher  sale  value  in  place  of  the  250,000  cost 
value  and  in  this  way  bring  down  not  the  income  but  the  apparent 
rate  of  interest.  Practicallv  all  state  forests  of  Germany  never  cost 


INTEREST  ON  LAND  8 1 

the  states  any  money,  they  were  simply  taken  charge  of  by  the  gov- 
ernments, paid  their  way  and  all  improvements  to  the  present  day. 
And  yet  their  value  is  set  so  high  that  the  splendid  net  income- bare- 
ly makes  3%,  in  most  cases  not  that.  The  strange  part  is  that  this 
high  value  is  not  a  fictitious  one  but  a  very  real  thing  and  that  these 
properties  could  readily  be  sold  at  these  high  prices. 

We  have  the  same  situation  in  the  case  of  farm  properties  in 
Europe  as  well  as  in  our  country. 

3.  Rate  of  interest  made  in  a  forestry  enterprise  starting 
with  bare  land. 

Under  this  head  come  the  ordinary  plantations,  where  no  forest 
exists,  where  the  bare  land  is  considered  as  the  real  capital,  where 
the  money  for  planting,  etc.,  is  or  may  be  borrowed  at  the  interest 
rate  used  in  the  calculation.  In  this  case  then : 

_  yearly  income  X  ioo     _  yearly  income  X  ioo   a  X  ioo 

capital  "    cost  value  of  land  Sc 

Since  the  income  here  is  not  a  yearly  one  but  a  periodic  one, 
every  r  years,  the  value  of  the  equivalent  yearly  income  may  be 
found  by  the  formula  : 

A  .( 


The  periodic  income  is : 

A  =  Yr  +  Ta(i.opr-a)— -  C(i.opr)  —  E(i.opr— i) 

and  the  above  calculation  for  yearly  income  is  then: 
(Yr  -j-  Ta(i.opr'a) — C(i.opr) — 'E(i.opr — i)  .op        ^ 

_  a  X  ioo       Se  .op  X  ioo  _  Se  . 

To  illustrate : 

If  the  land  costs  $10  per  acre,  the  accepted  rate,  p,  is  3%,  and 
the  forest  enterprise  is  such  that  it  pays  3%  on  $30,  i.  e.,  makes  the 
land  worth  $30,  then  evidently  the  man  makes  on  his  cost  value  of 
land  on  the  $10,  not  3%  but  9%,  or,  as  per  formula : 

30 

P*  =  —  X  3  or  9. 
10 

This  is  an  interesting  statement  and  has  value  especially  in  the 
United  States  where  cost  values  of  forest  lands  are  still  very  low. 


82  FOREST  VALUATION 

To  illustrate :  Cut  over  lands  in  the  southern  states  may  be  bought 
at  $2  per  acre.  The  Se  even  on  a  very  conservative  basis  is  $20 
per  acre.  To  a  company  financially  able  to  hold  and  develop  such 
lands  as  forest  properties  the  enterprise  would  make : 

20 

P*  =  —  3  =  30  %  on  the  cost  value  of  the  land. 
2 

It  should  be  noted  that  p  in  this  case  should  be  the  p  employed  in 
calculation  of  Se,  and  also  that  the  px,  the  30%  in  the  above  case, 
is  the  interest  made  only  on  the  cost  value  of  the  land,  on  Sc,  and 
that  the  other  parts  of  the  investment,  costs  of  planting,  taxes,  pro- 
tection, etc.,  produce  simply  p  the  accepted  rate  of  interest,  usually 
3%  in  these  studies. 


C.     COMPARISON  OF  PROPERTIES  WITH  YEARLY 
AND  WITH  INTERMITTENT  INCOME. 

The  great  advantage  of  having  any  kind  of  business  in  a  condi- 
tion of  producing  approximately  equal  and  yearly  incomes  is  quite 
evident.  Ordinarily  an  enterprise  is  not  considered  a  business  at 
all  until  it  does  produce  a  yearly  income  at  least  balancing  expenses. 
In  most  cases  it  is  difficult  to  interest  and  enlist  financial  support  or 
purchasers  unless  there  is  an  assured  yearly  return  at  least  equal  to  a 
conservative  rate  of  interest,  except  in  cases  where  a  body  of  nat- 
ural wealth  is  in  view,  as  in  standing  timber,  coal  veins,  etc.,  or  else 
in  cases  of  great  possibilities  or  probabilities  where  the  element  of 
lottery  or  gamble  enters.  Financial  concerns  under  public  control 
are  generally  forbidden  to  lend  on  securities  of  this  kind.  The  reg- 
ular yearly  income  has  been,  therefore,  one  of  the  aims  in  forest 
business  and  forms  one  of  the  principal  tasks  of  forest  regulation. 
Merely  to  emphasize  and  illustrate  this  fact  the  following  concrete 
case  is  here  considered. 

Assume  two  properties  of  1,000  acres  each;  rotation  80  years; 
p,  3%;  Yr,  $400;  Sc,  $10;  average  growth  of  ripe  stuff  per  acre, 
one  cord  per  year,  value  per  cord,  $4;  cost  of  planting,  c,  $10 ;  cur- 
rent expenses,  e,  $i  per  acre.  Thinnings  left  out  for  sake  of  sim- 
plicity. 


AND   INTERMITTENT 

Comparison  of  yearly  and  intermittent  working. 


Property    with    yearly 
cut    and    yearly    income. 


Property  with  a  cut 
and  income  every  80 
years. 


1.  Growing    stock    at 
beginning. 

2.  Growth  of  ripe  stuff 
during  the  80  years. 

3.  Growing    stock    at 
end  of  80  years. 

4.  Value   of   property 
at  beginning. 


5.  Income   during  the 
80  years. 

6.  Income  at  80,  i.  e., 
in  last  year. 

7-    Condition  at  end  of 
first   twenty  years : 


40,000  cords. 
80,000  cords. 
40,000  cords. 


$10,000  for  land  and 
about  $60,000  for  grow- 
ing stock. 

$320,000   plus    interest. 


$4,000. 


Has   Earned: 
Per  year  : 

Income :  4000. 
Expenses : 

Rent  335- 

Tax  and  care  1000. 

Planting  125. 

Total  expense  1460. 
Net  income  per  year, 

$2540. 
Net  income  for  20  years 

(i.03M— i) 
2540  —  —  or  about 

i  .01 — i 
$67,700. 


None. 


80,000  cords. 


80,000  cords. 


$10,000  for  land  noth- 
ing for  'growing  stock; 
might  enter  plantation. 

None,  thinnings  not 
considered. 

$320,000. 


In  Debt : 

Expenses  per  year : 
Rent  33-5. 

Tax  and  care  1000. 
Total  I335- 

For  20  years'  expenses : 
(I.0329— i) 

1335  -        or 

1.03—1 
$35,6oo. 

For  planting  10,000. 
Plus  interest  or 

1 0,000  ( i  .0320 )  —  1 8,000. 
Total  expenses  for  20 
years : 
$53,600. 


This  simple  case  of  a  comparatively  small  property  brings  out 
the  great  disadvantages  of  the  intermittent  working  of  a  forest  prop- 
erty. The  man  who  owns  1,000  acres  of  land  and  sees  before  him 


84  FOREST  VALUATION 

the  piling  up  of  over  $50,000  expenses  in  only  one-fourth  of  the  ro- 
tation is  not  very  much  encouraged  to  go  into  the  forest  business. 
It  also  illustrates  why  in  common  sense  and  fairness  the  owner  of 
such  a  property  is  not  able  to  pay  taxes  like  the  owner  of  a  regu- 
lated forest  who  has  a  net  income  every  year.  It  also  illustrates  the 
fairness,  in  fact  the  necessity,  of  deferring  the  taxes  to  the  time 
when  the  timber  is  cut  and  an  income  secured,  such  taxes  to  stand 
as  a  lien  against  the  property.* 

*  Read :  "The  Need  of  Working  Plans  on  National  Forests  and  the 
Policies  Which  Should  be  Embodied  in  Them,"  by  Professor  Burt  P.  Kirk- 
land,  in  Proceedings  of  the  Society  of  American  Foresters,  Oct.  1915.  This 
article  shows  clearly  the  necessity  of  working  for  a  sustained  yearly  cut  in 
the  forests,  and  the  principles  laid  down  in  this  article  apply  in  all  real  forestry 
work  the  world  over. 


V.    ROTATION 

In  planning  a  forest  business  it  becomes  necessary  to  decide 
upon  a  rotation.  To  do  this  is  one  of  the  most  important  tasks  of 
forest  regulation  and  requires  a  most  careful  consideration  of  all 
conditions  and  factors  concerned.  Among  these  the  most  impor- 
tant are  the  market,  site,  species  and  treatment. 

The  market  sets  its  requirements  as  to  species,  size  and  quality 
which  must  be  raised,  and  it  is  useless  to  discuss  rotations  which  fail 
to  raise  timber  of  the  required  size.  Site,  species,  and  treatment, 
particularly  practice  of  planting  and  thinning  decide  the  length  of 
time  in  which  the  desired  size  and  quality  of  timber  can  be  raised. 
Being  largely  a  weighing  of  conditions  and  factors,  the  setting  of 
the  rotation  is  primarily  a  problem  in  statics  and  perhaps  the  most 
important  task  of  statics  in  forestry. 

In  so  far  as  the  conditions  and  results  require  expression  in 
dollars  and  cents,  the  basis  for  the  study  of  a  proper  rotation  is  sup- 
plied by  forest  valuation.  In  any  ordinary  forest  business  the  aim 
is  to  keep  the  forest  and  land  in  best  possible  condition  and  at  the 
same  time  make  the  largest  income. 

Assuming  the  silvicultural  conditions  cared  for,  the  best  rota- 
tion is  the  one  furnishing  the  best  income  for  the  longest  time. 

There  are  two  distinct  ways  of  judging  this  income: 

1.  We  may  demand  the  largest  net  income  per  acre  of  estab- 
lished forest; 

2.  We  may  wish  to  secure  the  largest  per  cent  on  the  money 
invested  in  the  forest  or  the  largest  net  rental  on  the  soil,  the  max- 
imum Se. 

These  two  viewpoints  have  for  many  years  divided  the  foresters 
of  central  Europe  into  two  schools,  the  division  still  exists  and  prom- 
ises to  continue  for  a  long  time. 

a.     Rotation  for  largest  net  income  per  acre  of  forest. 

The  assumption  here  is  that  we  start  with  a  forest  and  not 
merely  bare  land ;  that  this  forest  is  more  or  less  regulated  and  able 
to  produce  a  yearly  income.  All  of  these  conditions  actually  apply 
to  the  majority  of  forest  properties  of  central  Europe. 

The  following  case  illustrates  the  calculation: 

Area  of  forest,  16,000  acres;  rotation,  80  years;  age  classes 
fairly  regular.  From  this  forest  we  can  select  an  80  acres  sample 


86 


ST  VALUATION 


with  stands  of  all  ages  from   1-80  years.     From  this   sample  we 
would  get  each  year  : 

One  acre  of  ripe  stuff  to  cut  or  Yr, 

Several  acres  of  thinnings,  or  3Tq, 

And  we  should  have  expenses  of  one  acre  to  plant,  or  c,  and 
80  acres  to  pay  taxes,  protection,  etc.,  or  re,  which  may  be  put  into 
the  following  form  : 
average  net  income  per  acre  = 


re 


or  according  to  the  following  table  for  spruce  site  II,  for  a  rotation 
of 

583+  71  —  12  —  54 

60  years =  $  9.80 

60 

980  +  232  —  12  —  72 

80  years  =  $14.10 

80 

Spruce  site  II,  Germany,  Endres,  after  Schwappach,  gross  in- 
come, expenses,  net  income  and  Se  for  different  rotations  from  30 
to  1 20  years  for  use  in  formula.  Average  net  income  per  acre 


Gross  Income. 

Expenses. 

Net  Income. 

re 

Se 

Yr  or 

2Tq 

m  Total 

current 

Total 

Total 

on  basis 

Rotation 
Years. 

final 
cut 
per 

sum  of 
thin- 
nings 

income 
from  r 
acres 

c 

plant- 
ing of 

expense 
tax,  pro- 
tection 

expense 
forr 
acres 

from 
r  acres 
of 

\verage 
per 

of  3% 
rental 
value 

acre 

from  r 

of 

one 

etc.,  for 

of 

normal 

acre. 

one  acre 

r  years 

acres. 

normal 

acre. 

r  acres 

normal 

forest. 

bare 

old. 

forest. 

e$o.9o 

forest. 

land 

$ 

$ 

$ 

$ 

$ 

$ 

$ 

$ 

$ 

30 

87 

87 

12 

27 

39 

48 

1.  00 

10 

40 

203 

7 

210 

12 

36 

48 

163 

4.00 

47 

50 

371 

3i 

402 

12 

45 

57 

354 

6.90 

77 

60 

583 

7i 

654 

12 

54 

66 

588 

9.80 

98 

70 

786 

137 

.923 

12 

63 

75 

848 

12.10 

105 

80 

980 

232 

1212 

12 

72 

84 

1129 

14^10 

105 

90 

1123 

35i 

1474 

12 

s7 

93 

1382 

15-30 

99 

100 

1222 

488 

I7IO 

12 

90 

102 

1609 

16.00 

91 

no 

I28l 

683 

1919 

12 

99 

III 

1808 

16.40 

83 

120 

I2Q6 

791 

2087 

12 

108 

1  2O 

1967 

16.30 

75 

FINANCIAL  ROTATION  87 

From  the  foregoing  table  it  appears  that  the  average  net  in- 
come with  spruce  site  II  and  present  prices,  is  but  $1.60  per  acre 
for  a  rotation  of  thirty  years,  rises  rapidly  and  steadily  to  $15.30 
for  a  ninety  year  rotation  and  passes  a  maximum  of  $16.40  at  a  rota- 
tion of  about  no  years. 

b.  Rotation  for  largest  net  rental  on  land,  maximum  Se, 
and  with  this  of  highest  per  .cent  interest  on  the  investment.  See 
also  chapter  on  Se.  The  assumption  is  that  the  bare  land  is  the 
real  capital  and  that  by  using  it  to  raise  timber  this  land  is  made  to 
pay  a  rental  and  the  object  is  to  decide  upon  a  rotation  which  will 
secure  the  highest  net  rental  per  acre,  i.  e.,  the  highest  Se. 

That  a  forest  producing  the  largest  Se  also  pays  the  largest  rate 
of  interest  or  p  is  evident  from  a  previous  study  into  p  where  it  is 
shown  that : 

Se 

px  =  —  p,  the  rate  of  p  on  Sc. 
Sc 

Since  Sc  or  the  cost  value  of  the  land  is  fixed  arid  p  is  the  accepted 
rate  of  interest  which  is  also  fixed,  it  is  evident  that  px  increases 
directly  with  Se.  This  calculation  applies  to  every  stand  or  every 
acre  in  the  forest  and  therfore  to  the  entire  property. 

Generally  longer  rotation  means  larger  and  better  timber,  larger 
growing  stock,  larger  capital,  larger  net  income  per  acre  of  property. 
As  seen  from  the  table  for  spruce}  site  II,  and  from  discussion  of 
Se  it  means  a  larger  Se  and  better  rate  of  interest.  But  this  reaches 
a  maximum  after  which  the  Se  and  with  it  the  rate  of  interest  made 
by  the  forest  decreases.  Formerly  unduly  long  rotations  and  large 
timber  were  the  rule  and  in  most  forest  districts  there  was  no  regard 
to  the  relation  of  this  rotation  with  the  capital  invested  and  the  in- 
come secured.  It  was  against  this  kind  of  luxury  in  forest  manage- 
ment that  Pressler  and  Heyer  raised  their  voices  and  used  the  math- 
ematics1 of  forest  valuation  and  statics.  And  it  was  the  fundamen- 
tal formula  for  Se  first  developed  by  Faustman  which  served  to 
make  clear  the  mistakes  of  very  long  rotations.  At  first  the  current 
rates  of  interest,  four  and  five  per  cent,  were  employed.  But  as 
seen  from  discussion  of  Se  these  higher  rates  not  only  reduce  Se 
but  bring  the  maximum  Se  very  early  and  so  suggest  or  demand 
too  short  rotations.  That  there  must  be  a  limit  to  shortening  of 
rotation  and  that  good  marketable  timber  must  be  raised  regardless 
of  any  formulae  was  evident  to  every  good  practitioner.  Unneces- 
sary stress  on  mathematical  formulae  on  the  one  side  and  common 
sense  with  an  aversion  for  formulae,  especially  for  bringing  in  com- 


88  FdREST  VALUATION 

pound  interest  discussions  into  the  business  of  raising  timber,  on 
the  other,  have  prevented  the  two  schools  from  coming  together. 

Of  late  there  is  a  better  understanding,  it  is  evident  to  all  that 
the  forest  must  produce  good  marketable  stuff,  and  that  if  the  for- 
est can  not  make  more  than  3%  in  doing  this,  there  is  little  use  of 
introducing  5%  in  the  formulae.  On  the  other  hand  it  is  clear  that 
the  planting  of  small  saplings  at  $50  per  acre  and  holding  old  stands 
which  have  not  earned  i%  for  a  quarter  of  a  century  are  mistakes 
to  be  avoided. 

With  an  interest  rate  of  2%,  the  rotation  of  highest  Se,  the 
financial  rotation  coincides  closely  with  the  technical  rotation  or 
that  producing  the  timber  most  in  demand  and  now  in  actual  use. 

A  few  figures  may  serve  to  illustrate  this : 

Ordinary  rotations  for  regular  timber  forest  in  central  Europe 
run  about  as  follows : 

Pine    and    spruce 80  to  100  years 

Balsam  and  beech TOO  to  120  years 

Oak    150  to  200  years 

For  spruce  in  Germany  as  seen  from  the  tables  under  discussion 
of  Se,  the  maximum  Se,  and  therfore  pf,  for  site  I-IV,  on  a  basis 
of  2%  comes  at  70-80  years,  at  a  3%  basis  in  60-70  years. 

For  pine  in  Germany  on  sites  I-IV,  on  a  basis  of  2%  as  well  as 
3%  the  maximum  Se  comes  at  60-70  years. 

For  balsam  in  Germany  according  to  Lorey,  maximum  Se  for 
sites  II-III  on  a  basis  of  2l/2%  comes  at  loo-no  years,  which  ac- 
cording to  Lorey  is  also  the  preferable  age  from  the  standpoint  of 
silviculture. 

For  oak  in  Germany,  according  to  Schwappach,  a  rate  of  2% 
puts  the  maximum  Se  at  120-130  years,  but  here  the  modern  tech- 
nical requirements  demand  a  rotation  of  160  or  over. 

For  beech  in  Germany  the  maximum  Se  on  2%  basis  for  sites 
I-IV  comes  at  about  80  years,  a  rotation  which  does  not  produce 
satisfactory  saw  timber  and  similar  goods. 

Poor  sites  such  as  poor  sands  in  the  pinery  of  north  Germany 
are  unable  with  any  rotation  to  make  a  3%  income  under  the  ordi- 
nary conditions  of  German  management,  and  barely  work  out  2% 
for  land  and  costs.  That  the  rotation  can  be  shortened  by  planting 
good  transplants  and  by  an  energetic  practice  of  thinning  is  evi- 
dent. In  addition,  the  modern  means  of  manufacture  have  made  it 
possible  to  use  smaller  sizes  and  so  work  toward  shorter  rotations 
in  the  forest. 


VI.    VALUE  OF  STUMPAGE 

Under  present  conditions  in  the  United  States  timber  is  gen- 
erally bought  and  sold  as  standing  timber  or  on  the  stump,  and 
usually  goes  with  the  land,  so  that  in  most  cases  it  is  really  a  sale 
of  the  forest,  i.  e.,  land  together  with  the  entire  growing  stock  and 
not  merely  a  sale  of  the  timber. 

In  these  ordinary  sales  of  timber  or  forest,  the  price  paid  is 
determined  merely  by  the  value  of  the  merchantable  timber  and  the 
rest  of  the  growing  stock  as  well  as  the  land  is  left  out  of  consid- 
eration, thrown  into  the  bargain.  Of  late,  especially  on  the  national 
forests  larger  sales  have  been  made  where  the  value  of  the  merchant- 
able timber  alone  was  concerned. 

In  some  cases,  timber,  whether  forest  or  timber  alone,  is  bought 
for  immediate  use  or  cutting,  in  other  cases  the  timber  is  bought 
years  ahead  with  a  view  of  supplying  a  regular  lumber  or  timber 
business,  or  else  just  for  speculation,  when  it  has  to  be  held  for 
years  before  any  return  is  secured  from  the  money  invested.  In  this 
way  a  great  variety  of  cases  arise,  each  having  its  own  peculiar  con- 
ditions as  to  time,  location,  market,  cost  of  exploitation,  etc. 

But  all  of  these  cases  have  a  few  fundamental  conditions  in 
common  and  these  only  can  here  be  considered. 

Timber,  here  only  merchantable  timber,  like  other  property  has 
three  forms  of  value :  cost,  sale,  and  expectation  value. 

A.     Cost  value  of  stumpage. 

1.  Where  timber  is  raised  the  cost  value  of  the  merchantable 
timber  can  be  determined  in  the  ways  before  described.     But  gen- 
erally the  time  between  planting  and  harvest  is  so  long,  that  this 
cost  value  is  rarely  considered,  and  mature  timber  even  in  central 
Europe  is  estimated  by  sale,  rather  than  cost  value.     But  it  is  well 
to  keep  in  mind  that  with  present  prices  of  timber  from  twelve  to 
twenty  dollars  per  M.  feet  b.m.  and  cut  into  logs  for  spruce  and 
pine,  the  per  cent  made  in  the  forest  business  is  generally  three  per 
cent  or  less,  so  that  present  prices  may  be  regarded  as  cost  prices 
with  three  per  cent  and  no  profit,  in  spite  of  the  fact  that  forestry 
pays  a  larger  net  rent  per  acre  than  farming. 

2.  Where  timber  is  bought  for  immediate  use,  as  is  much  of 
the  timber  purchased  on  national  forests,  etc.,  the  price  paid  is  the 
cost  value. 


90  FOREST  VALUATION 

But  where  timber  was  bought  years  ago,  in  advance  of  cutting. 
the  present  cost  value  involves  :  price  paid  ;  interest,  compound,  us- 
ually 5-6%  in  the  United  States  ;  taxes  with  compound  interest  ;  care 
of  property,  of  late  some  money  for  fire  protection,  with  interest; 
losses  by  fire,  theft,  insects,  windfall,  etc. 

Part  of  these  losses  is  made  up  by  growth,  but  in  most  cases 
it  is  not  safe  to  figure  on  any  material  growth.  On  large  areas  the 
growth  is  usually  balanced  by  decay,  on  smaller  areas,  the  decay  or 
lass  may  far  outrun  growth,  as  in  timber  infested  by  insects,  etc.  In 
these  cases  only  a  detailed  examination  determines  the  true  status. 
Leaving  out  this  very  uncertain  element  of  losses  by  fire,  etc.,  the 
cost  value  results  in  a  case  approximately  like  the  following  : 

Area,  2,000  acres;  price  paid  10  years  ago,  $40,000; 

Present  value  of  this  40,000  (i.o510)  =$65,160; 

Taxes  at  i%%  on  half  cost  price,  $300  per  year; 

Care  of  property  by  some  local  agent,  lawyer,  etc.,  together  with 
expenses  of  fire  control  and  occasional  visit  by  cruiser,  etc.,  $200 
per  year.  These  two  items  with  interest  : 


(300  -f-  200)  —  —  =  $6,200, 

1.05—1 

Total  cost,  $71,360,  or  nearly  double  the  original  cost  price. 

This  explains  a  common  phrase  among  timber  owners  in  the 
United  States  —  that  the  value  of  a  property  must  double  every  ten 
years  if  there  is  to  be  no  loss. 

B.     Sale  value  of  stumpage. 

This  may  be  considered  under  two  heads  : 

The  ordinary  market  price  of  stumpage  as  determined  by  actual 
sales. 

The  stumpage  value  for  immediate  use  as  determined  by  an  an- 
alysis of  the  various  factors  entering  into,  or  affecting  this  value. 

i.  The  ordinary  market  price  of  stumpage  should  approxi- 
mate :  value  of  lumber  at  mill  —  cost  of  logging  and  milling,  where 
a  proper  profit,  etc.,  forms  part  of  costs. 

But  so  far  the  market  price  of  stumpage  has  not  been  deter- 
mined in  this  way.  Probably  more  than  ninety  per  cent  of  all  stump- 
age  bought  during  the  past  twenty-five  years  was  paid  at  prices  quite 
independent  of  the  prices  of  lumber  and  cost  of  logging,  and  deter- 
mined chiefly  by  the  activity  of  large  buyers.  A  number  of  causes 
contributed  to  this  peculiar  condition.  Large  quantities,  thousands 
of  acres  of  fine  stumpage  were  secured  without  pay  from  the  United 


STUMPAGK  AND  DISCOUNT  gi 

States  government  under  the  homestead  act,  large  areas  were  alien- 
ated at  the  nominal  price  of  two  dollars  and  a  half  per  acre  under 
the  Timber  and  Stone  act  and  by  Commutation  of  homesteads,  large 
areas  were  given  as  land  grants  to  railways,  etc.  Several  of  our 
states,  Florida,  Oregon,  Idaho,  New  Mexico  and  others  sold  lands, 
given  them  by  the  government  under  various  acts,  at  prices  in  no 
way  graded  by  the  price  of  lumber.  Even  our  lake  states  sold  tim- 
ber at  give-away  prices.  In  this  way  Michigan  sold  il/2  million 
acres  of  land  in  the  ten  years  ending  1910,  at  prices  usually  below 
two  dollars  per  acre  and  most  of  it  below  a  dollar  and  a  quarter, 
and  most  of  this  land  was  bought  for  the  timber.  Large  areas  of 
timberlands  have  been  held  by  small  owners,  or  owners  financially 
unable  to  exploit  and  market  the  materia.1  and  in  many  cases,  a  lack 
of  market,  transportation  facilities,  etc.,  prevented  the  owners  from 
doing  anything  with  the  timber.  Aside  from  these  personal  factors 
there  has  always  been  the  great  balance  of  demand  and  supply.  Even 

»  today  with  more  than  fifty  years  cut  in  sight,  of  timber  already  ma- 
tured, it  is  useless  to  estimate  the  value  on  a  basis  of  immediate  ex- 
ploitation and  present  prices. 

To  illustrate :  assuming  prices  of  lumber,  mill  run,  to  stay  at 
about  $15  per  M.  feet,  and  cost  of  logging  and  milling  to  average 
$10  per  M.  feet.  '  Then  the  true  value  of  stumpage  should  be  $5 
per  M.  feet  average. 

But  this  is  not  true.  The  first  year's  cut  is  worth  the  $5,  but 
the  second,  third,  etc.  year's  cut  is  not  worth  it.  The  stumpage  cut 
in  the  .tenth,  twentieth  or  thirtieth  year,  at  five  per  cent  discount  is 

5.00    5.00    5.00 

worth  only  -   — ,  -    — ,  -    — ,  or  $3.10,  $1.89  and  $1.15  per  M.  feet. 
1.62    2.65    4.32 

»In  keeping  with  these  peculiar  and  unsettled  conditions  of  stumpage 
prices  stumpage  of  pine  in  Minnesota  brought  $12  while  in  the 
same  year  millions  of  better  stumpage  was  bought  in  Oregon  for 
less  than  $i  per  M.  feet. 

The  man  in  Minnesota  could  use  it  at  once  and  make  money, 
the  man  in  Oregon  bought  it  to  hold  and  he  had  to  hold,  and  may 
lose  money  at  it. 

Stumpage  prices  today  vary  not  only  for  species  but  vary  with 
locality,  with  market,  railway  facilities,  habit  of  the  people  of  the 
district,  etc.  Average  figures  for  stumpage  have  little  value,  they 
vary  chiefly  between  $3  and  $7,  go  as  high  as  $20  and  as  low  as  $i, 
and  generally  make  from  10  to  30%  of  the  value  of  the  lumber  at 
the  mill. 


92 


FOREST  VALUATION 


In  central  Europe  most  of  the  timber  is  cut,  or  cut  and  skidded 
to  the  road  and  sold  not  really  as  stumpage  but  as  logs  ready  for 
hauling.  Here  the  prices  have  gradually  settled  to  a  fairly  exact 
condition,  the  value  of  the  logs  depending  on  mill  or  market  value, 
and  cost  of  transportation. 

The  prices  vary  little  from  year  to  year,  have  risen  steadily  for 
many  years,  about  doubled,  in  Germany  in  the  last  sixty  years.  The 
timber  is  bought  at  auction,  the  bids  usually  naming  a  per  cent  of 
the  price  set  by  the  forest  office. 

In  pine  and  spruce  the  timber  is  classified  by  the  cubic  contents 
of  the  stem,  i.  e.,  the  number  of  cubic  feet  per  stem.  The  following 
figures  illustrate : 

Spruce,  logs  cut  full  length,  ready  to  haul: 


Stem  Class: 

Contents  : 

Price  per  c.  ft. 

Price  M.  ft.  bm. 

Class  I 

100  c.  ft.  or  over 

14  cts.  per  c.  ft. 

$20 

Class  II 

70-100  c.    ft. 

13  cts.  per  c.  ft. 

$19 

Class  III 

35-  70  c.   ft. 

ii  cts.  per  c.  ft. 

$17 

Class  IV 

18-  35   c.   ft. 

10  cts.  per  c.  ft. 

$15 

Pine,  stems  cut  full  length,  ready  to  haul : 


Stem  Class: 

Contents  : 

Price  per  c.   ft. 

Price  M.  ft.  bm. 

Class  I 

70  c.  ft.  or  over 

15  cts. 

$22 

Class  II 

35-70  c.   ft. 

13  cts. 

$19 

Class  III 

18-35  c.  ft. 

9  cts 

$13 

Class  IV 

below  18  c.  ft. 

7  cts. 

$10 

Cordwood :  4  cts.  solid,  or  $3.60  per  cord. 


White  oak,  classification  by  middle  diameter  of  stem: 


Stem  Class  : 

Middle    Diameter  : 

Price  per  c.  ft. 

Price  M.  ft.  bm. 

Class  I 

24  inches  and  over 

42  cts. 

$60 

Class  II 

20-24 

35  cts. 

$50 

Class  III 

16-20 

28  cts. 

$40 

Class  IV 

12-16 

17  cts. 

$20 

Class  V 

under  12 

10  cts. 

$10 

VALUE;  OF  STUM  PAGE: 


93 


Beech  usually  sells  at  4-7  cents  per  cubic  foot  and  most  of  it, 
even  clear  logs  12  inches  diameter  and  better  go  as  cordwood.  This 
cordwood  is  commonly  sold  from  $3~$4  per  cord. 

Table  of  size  and  value  of  average  tree,  all  for  site  I : 


Age 

Pine. 

Spruce 

Oak 

Beech 

Diam.  " 

Value 

Dbh.  " 

Value 

Dbh.  " 

Value 

Dbh.  " 

Value 

60 

9-5 

$1.10 

9.0 

2-35 

8 

0.85 

8 

•55 

80 

12 

2.90 

12.6 

4-5<> 

12 

3 

10.8 

1.30 

100 

14 

4-50 

15-8 

8.30 

16 

9.80 

13 

2.25 

120 

16 

6.80 

18.4 

11.40 

18 

22.50 

15 

3-25 

140 

17.2 

9.60 

21.5 

28 

16.8 

4.20 

160 

23 

34 

180 

24-5 

48 

200 

26 

52 

The  above  prices  are  for  straight,  well-cleaned,  sound  timber. 
They  clearly  indicate  that  prices  in  parts  of  the  United  States  are 
rapidly  approaching  and  in  many  cases  have  fully  reached  those 
paid  in  the  forests  of  south  Germany  and  other  European  countries. 
In  fact  it  is  doubtful  if  the  same  grade  of  large  stems  could  be 
bought  for  the  same  prices  in  Ohio  or  Indiana  and  several  other 
states. 

2.  Sale  value  of  stumpage,  determined  by  consideration  of 
the  various  factors.  Here  the  calculation  attempts  to  show : 

price  of  lumber  at  mill ; 

cost  of  logging  and  milling ; 

the  assumption  being  that  the  stumpage  price  should  be  the  dif- 
ference between  these  two,  i.  e.,  if  the  lumber  is  worth  $15  and  it 
costs  $10  to  log  and  mill  then  the  stumpage  should  be  $5. 

a.     Price  of  lumber  at  mill. 

Where  the  lumber  is  sold  "mill  run"  this  value  is  easily  obtained 
providing  the  sale  of  the  lumber  is  bona  fide  and  under  normal  con- 
ditions. 

Where  lumber  is  graded  at  mill  and  sold  by  grades  to  various 
dealers,  attempts  are  made  to  get  at  the  true  average  price  by  learn- 
ing the  per  cent  each  grade  makes  of  the  cut  and  the  price  of  each 
grade. 

In  some  cases  this  is  quite  simple,  in  most  it  is  not.  Any  change 
in  the  quality  of  the  timber  in  the  woods  affects  the  per  cent  of 


94  FOREST  VALUATION 

grades.  Where  several  species  are  logged  together  such  as  hemlock, 
maple  and  beech,  etc.,  the  proportion  as  well  as  the  quality  vary 
from  one  tract  to  another. 

To  use  the  general  prices  of  the  district  and  agree  on  some  pro- 
portion of  kinds  and  grades  is  usually  as  far  as  the  analysis  can  go. 

b.     Cost  of  milling. 

This  also  involves  various  considerations  differing  radically  for 
different  cases.  In  one  case  the  logs  go  to  an  established  mill,  the 
particular  body  of  timber  is  only  one  of  several-  or  many  which  are 
cut  at  this  mill.  The  large  mills  along,  or  at  the  mouths  of  the 
rivers  in  Michigan  and  Wisconsin  are  of  this  order.  In  this  case 
the  cost  of  milling  is  quite  simple,  there  is  a  regular  market  value 
of  this  milling  toll  which  is  fairly  well  established. 

In  other  cases  the  mill  is  established  to  cut  the  particular  body 
of  timber  and  no  more,  it  must  be  torn  down  and  moved  away,  is 
largely  a  loss  and  with  it  also  a  number  of  other  buildings,  quarters 
for  men,  boarding  houses,  office,  store,  shops,  etc.  In  such  a  case 
the  cost  of  milling  involves : 

1.  Labor,  material  and  repairs; 

2.  Depreciation  of  all  buildings  and  machinery; 

3.  Interest,  taxes,  insurance,  supervision  and  profits. 
Generally  the  direct  cost  of  labor  and  materials  is  fairly  well 

known,  varies  within  narrow  limits,  mostly  between  $1.50  and  $3 
per  M.  feet  b.m. 

The  depreciation  of  mill  and  machinery  and  buildings  may  be 
treated  as  follows : 

Mill  and  buildings  may  be  assumed  to  last  throughout  the  job, 
the  different  machines  may  and  may  not  need  separate  treatment. 
Suppose  the  amount  of  stumpage  sufficient  to  furnish  10  years  cut- 
ting. Let  the  mill  and  other  buildings,  including  those  machines 
which  are  fairly  certain  to  last  the  ten  years  be  worth  $150,000  and 
let  the  interest  rate  be  5%.  Then  this  outfit  together  with  interest 
costs  at  the  end  of  the  ten  years : 

150,000  (i.O510) — the  wrecking  value  of  the  outfit. 

If  the  latter  is  $10,000,  then  the  end  value  is  240,000 —  10,000 
or  $230,000. 

Usually  we  desire  to  know  what  yearly  sum  will  take  care  of 
this  $230,000  and  from  this  derive  the  cost  of  the  depreciation  per 
M.  feet  of  lumber.  To  get  this  we  may  set  for  the  above  case: 

(i.o510— i) 

yearly  cost  of  depreciation  =  X  and  X =  $230,000,  and 

1.05—1 
from  this  X  =  $18,400. 


COST   OF   DUMBER  95 

If  the  yearly  cut  is  20  million  the  depreciation  is  92  cents  per 
M.  feet.  It  should  be  noted  that  this  92  cents  pays  for  this  part  of 
the  outfit  including  all  interests. 

c.     The  cost  of  logging. 

Logging  is  a  very  simple  kind  of  business  but  the  conditions 
under  which  it  is  done  are  variable  and  many,  and  tend  to  complicate 
matters.  Size  and  quantity  of  timber  per  acre,  mixture  of  species, 
mixture  of  large  and  small  stuff,  distances,  topography,  surface, 
rocks,  brush,  swamp,  weather,  snow,  etc.,  all  exert  their  influence. 
The  men  are  scattered  over  a  large  area  and  not  easily  supervised. 
Where  the  timber  is  large  as  in  the  Pacific  coast  country  or  located 
in  swamps  as  cypress  so  that  heavy  machinery  must  be  employed 
the  matter  is  made  still  more  difficult. 

Nevertheless  the  cost  of  logging  like  milling  varies  within  nar- 
row limits,  the  good  parts  of  the  job  making  up  for  the  bad.  Us- 
ually it  may  be  said  that  the  cost  of  logging  varies  from  4  to  6  dol- 
lars per  M.  feet  b.m.,  rarely  going  below  4,  occasionally  going  up 
to  8  in  mountain  country.  For  eastern  United  States  it  runs  per  M. 
feet  logs  about  as  follows : 

Felling  and  cutting  into  logs $  .75 

Skidding   and   swamping i  .25 

Hauling  to  landing  or  railway 1 .50 

Railway  haul  or  drive I .  oo 

Overhead  charges  of  supervision  replacement  of  equip- 
ment, teams,  camps,  roads 1 .50 


$6.00 

In  these  items  the  profit  is  included  with  each  item. 
For  large  timber  on  the  Pacific  coast : 

Felling  and  cutting  into  logs $  .60 

Yarding   and   loading 1 .00 

Hauling  to   mill i .  50 

Booming,    scaling,    etc 40 


Direct  costs    $3-5o 

Depreciation  of  machinery  and  wire  cables  on  basis  of 
the  time  they  last  and  how  many  millions  they 
handle,  also  railway  track  and  rolling  stock,  etc $2.00 

Taxes,  insurance,  interest  on  money  invested,  super- 
vision and  profit i .  50 

$7.00 


96  FOREST  VALUATION 

Usually  logging  is  cheaper  in  the  Great  Lakes  country  and 
South  than  in  East  and  West.  But  these  general  average  figures 
are  little  more  than  guide  marks,  each  job  has  its  own  peculiarities 
and  it  is  not  easy  to  standardize  where  considerations  are  so  varia- 
ble and  where  the  human  element  is  so  very  important. 

Logging  as  done  in  the  United  States  is  the  work  of  a  transition 
period,  many  of  the  methods  will  disappear,  simpler  methods  under 
more  uniform  conditions  will  take  their  place.  When  that  time 
comes  the  cost  of  logging  in  the  United  States  as  is  now  the  case 
in  many  of  the  forest  districts  of  Europe,  may  be  predicted  within 
very  close  limits. 

Where  the  sale  of  stumpage  involves  large  amounts  of  timber, 
requiring  ten  or  more  years  to  remove,  though  cutting  begins  at 
once,  the  case  of  sale  value  grades  into  the  expectation  value,  and 
demands  special  consideration.  On  the  national  forests  large  bodies 
of  timber  are  sold,  the  timber  is  paid  for  as  it  is  cut,  the  buyer  does 
not  really  own  the  stumpage,  he  takes  no  risks  in  case  of  fire  or  other 
injury,  except  so  far  as  the  injury  affects  his  camps,  equipment  and 
the  use  of  his  outfit  or  investments.  In  this  case  he  not  only  can 
pay  full  stumpage  value  as  calculated  above  but  can  pay  higher 
prices  for  stumpage  as  the  prices  of  lumber  increase.  For  this  rea- 
son provision  is  made  in  these  contracts  to  review  or  re-arrange  the 
price  scale  at  fixed  intervals  or  on  a  particular  scale. 

C.     Expectation  value  of  stumpage. 

Leaving  out  the  question  of  timberland  speculation  there  still 
arise  many  cases  where  this  value  is  involved.  In  buying  a  large 
lumber  business,  mill,  railway  equipment  and  body  of  timber,  the 
first  question  is:  what  is  the  timber  worth?  Suppose  the  concern 
has  four  hundred  million  feet  or  twenty  years'  supply  of  stumpage, 
the  present  value  of  stumpage  for  immediate  use  being  five  dollars 
per  M.  feet.  Evidently  it  would  be  a  mistake  to  pay  for  the  four 
hundred  million  at  the  rate  of  five  dollars  per  M.  feet  unless  the 
buyer  is  very  certain  that  the  increase  in  value  of  lumber  warrants 
this.  How  much  increase  would  this  mean? 

If  he  pays  $5  per  M.  feet,  or  2  million  dollars  for  the  400  mil- 
lion feet,  and  if  money  is  worth  5%.  then  this  sum  grows  to  2  mil- 
lion X  (J-OS20)  °r  $5>3OO>OO°  m  round  numbers.  The  lumber  val- 
ues do  not  rise  year  by  year  but  rise  by  groups  of  years  usually,  and 
with  this  rises  the  value  of  stumpage.  Assume  that  the  stumpage 
stays  at  $5  for  the  first  10  years  and  then  rises  to  a  constant  figure 
for  the  second  TO  years,  how  much  must  this  be?  About  $13  per 
'M.  feet 


EXPECTATION  VALUE  OF  STUMPAGE  97 

If  he  pays  $5  and  stumpage  does  not  rise  he  loses  upwards  of 
two  million  dollars  in  the  twenty  years.  What  can  he  pay  if  he 
expects  stumpage  to  stay  at  $5?  About  $3.10  per  M.  feet. 

In  these  calculations  no  attention  is  paid  to  expenses,  taxes,  pro- 
tection, etc.,  which  the  owner  has  to  incur  in  holding  these  forest 
lands.  The  way  of  computing  these  was  indicated  under  cost  value 
of  stumpage  and  in  other  connections. 

From  what  has  been  said  about  stumpage  valuation  it  is  evi- 
dent that  in  most  cases  it  is  a  matter  of  business  judgment  and  inti- 
mate knowledge  of  conditions  which  guides  the  investor.  This 
knowledge  is  largely  one  of  forest  utilization.  The  methods  of  cal- 
culation or  arrangement  of  data  present  nothing  new  but  follow  the 
general  lines  of  forest  valuation. 

The  traffic  in  stumpage  as  it  has  existed  in  the  United  States 
up  to  the  present  time  will  be  modified  in  time  and  take  more  and 
more  the  form  of  timber  sale  now  in  use  on  the  national  forests  and 
in  the  more  settled  districts  change  to  the  form  of  timber  disposal 
now  in  use  in  central  Europe.  Good  silviculture  will  press  steadily 
for  full  control  of  the  timber  cutting. 


VII.    DAMAGES  IN  TIMBER 


Here  belong  a  great  variety  of  cases,  from  gas  injury  of  shade 
trees  in  the  town  to  the  burning  of  large  bodies  of  timber  by  fires 
started  by  a  railway  locomotive.  And  it'  is  not  merely  the  cases 
where  someone  is  liable  or  supposed  to  be  so,  but  the  numberless 
additional  cases  where  it  is  part  of  the  forest  business  to  ascertain 
damages  done  by  fire,  storm,  insects,  etc. 

Normally,  the  damage  is  only  to  the  live,  growing  trees,  but  at 
times  there  is  added  damage,  since  it  may  cost  considerable  sums 
to  put  the  land  in  shape  for  a  new  crop.  Commonly  these  cases  are 
complicated.  A  fire  running  through  a  stand  of  hardwoods  may  kill 
half  the  trees  and  leave  the  rest  in  an  injured  condition  so  that  a 
few  survive  staying  alive  for  twenty  years,  while  most  of  them  die 
during  the  first  five  years.  In  such  cases  it  is  anything  but  easy  to 
determine  the  exact  facts,  or  condition. 

Such  cases  are  usually  complicated  still  further  by  the  fact  that 
parts  or  all  of  the  timber  could  be  used  if  cut  at  once,  but  that  various 
circumstances  prevent  the  owner  from  cutting,  so  it  may  be  several 
years  before  he  gets  to  all  of  the  lands  burned  over  and  in  this  way 
loses  nearly  all  of  the  timber.  How  far  conditions  compel  him  and 
how  far  he  is  at  fault  himself  is  usually  impossible  to  ascertain  accu- 
rately. 

Only  a  few  sample  cases  may  be  considered  here : 

a.     The  shade  tree  in  town. 

A  tree  forty  years  old,  satisfactory  in  every  way,  is  destroyed 
by  a  gas  leak.  What  is  the  true  value  destroyed  ?  The  owner  guid- 
ed by  his  feelings  would  probably  place  the  value  at  several  hun- 
dred, the  person  responsible  for  the  leak  would  value  it  as  fire  wood. 

The  following  calculation  may  be  helpful  and  approach  a  just 
settlement  as  nearly  as  possible : 

Cost  of  establishing  a  good  tree,  $15 ;  interest  at  5%  ;  25  years 
before  the  tree  is  really  serving  its  purpose,  after  that  the  tree  pays 
its  way,  pays  by  its  service  as  shade  tree  interest  on  the  cost  of  es- 
tablishing it. 

The  value  of  the  tree  is  then  15  (i.O523)  =$51.80  and  this  val- 
ue remains  as  long  as  the  tree  is  in  good  condition.  Cost  of  caring 
for  the  tree,  etc.,  might  also  be  added. 


DAMAGE  ESTIMATES  99 

b.  Young  plantation  of  forest  trees. 

Spruce  twenty-five  years  old  destroyed  by  fire;  evidently  the 
stuff  is  of  little  use  save  as  inferior  fire  wood.  Assuming  the  cost 
value  of  the  stand  to  be  forty-five  dollars  and  the  value  of  the  dam- 
aged wood  to  be  ten  dollars  per  acre  the  real  damage  is  clearly  thir- 
ty-five dollars. 

If  the  wood  is  of  no  value  and  the  man  spends  ten  dollars  per 
acre  to  get  the  land  cleared  sufficiently  to  plant  another  crop,  the 
loss  to  him  is  fifty-five  dollars.  In  the  past  the  courts  in  the  United 
States  judged  the  value  of  the  timber  solely  as  sale  value.  Since 
the  timber  on  this  plantation  has  no  sale  value  and  since  the  man 
actually  incurred  these  losses  it  is  only  fair  that  he  should  receive 
pay  accordingly. 

To  ask  damages  in  proportion  to  an  expectation  value  of  this 
stand,  on  assumption  that  at  the  age  of  eighty  years,  or  fifty-five 
years  hence,  the  stand  may  be  worth  five  hundred  dollars  an  acre, 
while  perfectly  reasonable,  would  not  appeal  to  any  court  of  justice. 

c.  Older  plantation  of  pine. 

Fifty-year-old  stand  completely  destroyed,  sale  value  is  only  one 
hundred  and  twenty  dollars  an  acre,  but  the  expectation  value  on  an 
eighty  year  rotation  is  two  hundred  dollars.  Which  should  be  al- 
lowed? Evidently  the  latter,  or  at  least  a  compromise  between  sale 
and  expectation  value.  In  this  case  the  costs  of  establishing  the 
stand  are  remote ;  it  may  have  been  natural  reproduction  on  non- 
agricultural  land,  etc.,  and  might  be  less  than  fifty  dollars.  So  it 
would  not  be  fair  to  restrict  the  price  to  this  cost  value.  On  the 
other  hand,  expensive  planting  on  costly  land  and  much  extra  care, 
cultivating,  etc.,  might  bring  the  cost  value  to  two  hundred  and 
fifty  dollars,  which  in  all  probability  would  not  be  allowed. 

d.  Ordinary  Stand  of  wild  woods. 

Timber  on  forty  acres  of  hardwoods  and  hemlock  is  largely 
destroyed  by  fire.  History  and  conditions  of  the  forty  acres  of 
forest:  bought  12  years  ago  at  $800;  interest  rate  5%;  ready  to 
cut  7  years  from  now ;  timber  400  M.  feet,  present  stumpage  price 
$5  per  M.  feet ;  land  now  worth  $10  per  acre  when  cut  over ;  expect 
stumpage  to  go  to  $6  in  the  next  7  years.  Value  of  timber  after 
fire,  $500 ;  tax  and  care  for  the  40,  $30  per  year. 


100  FOREST  VALUATION 

Estimate  of  the  damage  may  be  set  in  one  of  three  ways  : 
I.     By  cost  value: 

Value  before  fire :  $800  (i.os12) $  1434 

30  (i. OS12— 0 
Tax  and  care —  —    480 

(1.05—1) 


Total    $  1914 

Value  after  fire: 

Land $400 

Timber    500 

Total    - $900 

damage,  $1,014. 

2.  By  sale  value : 

Value  before  fire :  land  $400 

Timber   400  X  5    2000 

Total    $2400 

damage,  $1,500. 

In  this  case  it  must  be  shown  that  the  sale  value  could  actually 
be  obtained  without  delay.  The  fact  that  timber  is  worth  $5  stump- 
age  in  the  particular  district  is  not  sufficient  evidence. 

3.  By  expectation  value : 
Expectation  value  of  the  40  before  fire : 

Value  of  timber  400  X  6 $2400 

Value   of    land 400 


Total  gross  value  in  7  years. $2800 

Expenses  during  7  years: 
3o(i.o57— i) 


.$  244 


1.05—1 

2556 

Present  value  1817 

i.o57 

Value  after  fire,  $900;  damage,  $917. 

In  cases  of  this  kind  the  value  of  the  young  stuff,  i.  e.,  the  non- 
merchantable  part  of  the  growing  stock  is  usually  left  out  of  the 
calculation,  though  frequently  it  has  a  greater  value  than  the  mer- 
chantable stuff. 


ESTIMATE:  BY  AVERAGE  YEARLY  GROWTH  ioi 

e.     Young  Stands  in  Wild  Woods. 

In  the  more  remote  districts  of  the  United  States  the  value  of 
the  land,  and  the  value  of  young,  or  non-merchantable  timber  is  de- 
batable. The  determination  of  the  cost  of  production  of  such  a 
stand,  with  calculations  of  compound  interest,  rent,  charge  of  pro- 
tection, etc.,  is  not  well  understood,  and  not  well  received,  and  the 
same  is  even  more  true  with  regard  to  the  expectation  value. 

For  such  cases  it  has  been  suggested  to  use  a  method  strongly 
advocated  for  years  by  Frey  in  Germany  (See  Zeitschirft  fur  F. 
and  J.,  1915,  p.  284),  and  employ  the  sale  value  exclusively  as  the 
basis  of  estimate.  Ordinarily  this  would  work  out  about  as  follows : 

The  ripe  stand,  120  years  old,  is  worth  $300.    A  stand  40  years 

300X40 

old  is  worth—          — .     Generally,  then,  the  value  of  any  stand  is 
120 

based  on  the  average  yearly  growth  in  value,  in  the  above  case: 

300 

—  —  $2.50  per  acre  and  year.     Due  allowance  is  made  for  de- 


120 

gree  of  stocking  or  condition  of  the  stand. 

The  advantage  of  this  method  lies  in  its  simplicity;  it  expects 
the  trespasser  to  pay  only  for  the  wood  actually  on  the  ground  and 
destroyed.  For  stands  older  than  one-half  the  rotation  this  method 
is  satisfactory;  for  young  stands  it  does  not  quite  do  justice  to  the 
owner.  Thus  if  a  plantation  is  destroyed  4  years  after  being  estab- 
lished the  $2.50  per  acre  and  year  (in  above  case)  would  hardly  clean 
the  ground  and  replant,  and  the  owner  would  have  nothing  for  the 
four  years'  growth  and  expenses.  To  charge  the  cost  of  planting 
and  protection,  etc.,  to  the  $10.00  actual  value  per  acre,  in  this  case, 
is  really  to  ask  pay  for  the  stand  twice,  once,  its  actual  value,  and 
once  on  basis  of  cost  of  production,  or  at  least  a  large  part  of  this. 

Where  natural  reproduction  is  assumed  to  require  10-20  years 
time,  this  period  of  reproduction  is  made  part  of  the  rotation ;  i.  e., 
the  rotation  includes  the  entire  time  from  one  harvest  to  the  next. 
For  the  above  case  the  crop  worth  $300  is  produced  in  120  years. 
If  an  additional  16  years  is  required  for  natural  reproduction  the 

300 

average  yearly  growth  is :  -  —  =  $2.20  per  acre  and  year.    In 

120 -h  16 

the  usual  case  of  natural  reproduction  a  stand  of  trees  with  an  aver- 
age of  20  years  may  contain  trees  from  about  12  to  28  years  old; 


102  FOREST  VALUATION 

the  land  has  been  occupied  and  used  for  28  years,  and  the  question 
arises :  should  the  trespasser  pay  for  a  stand  20  years  old  or  one  28 
years  old?  Evidently  the  latter,  at  least  in  all  cases  of  clear  cutting. 
In  the  shelter-woods  where  an  old  stand  shares  in  the  growth  dur- 
ing the  16  years  in  which  the  new  stand  is  established,  it  may  suffice 
to  charge  for  20  years'  growth. 

It  is  evident  that  this  method  of  computing  the  value  of  the 
stand  lacks  analysis  and  must  always  be  defective  especially  with 
young  stands,  where  the  computation  of  the  regular  cost  value  of 
stand  is  much  more  satisfactory. 

f.     The  lumberman's  case. 

Two  years  after  the  fire,  claimedly  caused  by  the  locomotive 
of  a  railway  company,  the  lumber  company  sues  the  railway  com- 
pany and  claims :  Lumber  company  bought,  merely  as  "permit"  or 
"license,"  from  the  Canadian  province,  460  million  feet  stumpage, 
it  had  cut  three  years  and  still  owned  400  million  feet,  it  has  the  right 
to  continue  lumbering  on  the  "timber  limit"  as  long  as  there  is  any 
timber;  it  pays  50  cents  per  M.  feet  "royalty,"  or  stumpage ;  it  in- 
vested $200,000  in  mill,  railway  and  equipment,  and  aimed  to  cut 
the  timber  in  next  20  years  ;  was  making  a  profit  of  $2  per  M.  feet 
in  the  business.  The  fire  destroyed  200  million  and  so  reduced  the 
cut  by  nearly  10  years,  since  most  of  the  timber  destroyed  is  not 
yet  accessible. 

The  particular  claim  set  forth: 

1.  Lump  sum  to  cover  loss  in  manufacture  of  lumber  and  for 
increased  cost  of  logging  due  to  reduction  of  total  stand  available 
for  the  plant. 

2.  Value  of  stumpage  actually  destroyed. 

3.  Value    of    equipment,    camps,    railway    bridges,    etc.,  de- 
stroyed. 

4.  Logs  and  ties  burned  up. 

5.  Value  of  young  timber.,  not  yet  merchantable,  destroyed. 

Among  the  questions  which  came  up  were  the  following: 

1.  Is  all  dead  timber  on  the  area  killed  by  the  particular  fire? 

2.  Is  all  dead  timber  actually  a  loss,  and  if  not  how  much  has 
been  saved,  how  much  could  be  saved,  and  at  what  gain  ? 

3.  What  is  the  company's  basis  for  claiming  that  it  can  make 
$2  per  M.  feet,  and  how  is  this  affected  by  future  logging  from  more 
remote  portions  of  the  tract? 

4.  What  effort  did  the  company  make  to  protect  its  logs  and 
equipment  ? 


LUMBERMAN  s  CASE:  103 

5.  What  right  has  the  company  to  claim  pay  for  immature  stuff 
when  the   forest  belongs  to   the  province   and  the   company   pays 
stumpage  as  it  cuts  ? 

6.  Is  not  the  province  the  real  owner  of  the  stumpage  and  the 
one  entitled  to  pay  for  stumpage  destroyed? 

7.  What   rate   of   interest   should   be   used   in   calculation   of 
damages  ? 

Other  complications  came  up  but  need  no  mention  here.  Evi- 
dently claim  numbers  five  and  two  for  young  stuff  and  stumpage  re- 
quires a  court  decision  as  to  rights  of  a  "limit  holder."  If  favorable, 
then  the  expectation  value  or  Ge  should  be  established  on  basis  of 
growth  study,  and  cruise. 

Claims  three  and  four  are  clearly  right,  if  properly  substan- 
tiated. 

Claims  one  and  two  are  not  easily  separated  since  one  depends 
on  two.  The  simplest  calculation  is  offered  by  establishing  the  in- 
come or  expectation  value  of  the  whole  business  before  the  fire  and 
the  same  value  after  the  fire  and  the  difference  should  be  the  loss. 

Expectation  value  before  the  fire:  the  cut  is  20  million  feet 
per  year  with  profit,  (evidently  net  income  and  profit),  $2  per  M. 
feet,  or  a  total  of  $40,000  per  year;  interest  -at  3%  ;  since  this  would 
have  continued  for  20  years  the  present  value  of  these  20  years 
income  is  : 


plus  the  provable  wrecking  value  of  the  outfit  at  end  of  20  years, 
discounted  to  present  time;  let  this  be  10,000,  then  the  total  is 
$601,000. 

The  expectation  value  after  the  fire  on  basis  of  only  $1.50  profit, 
due  to  extra  work  of  logging. 


30000 


i.o3-i 


plus  the  wrecking  value  at  end  of  ten  years,  discounted  to  present 
time  ;  if  this  is  $50,000,  then  the  present  value  is  $307,000,  and  the 
loss  due  to  fire  is  about  $294,000. 

Another  way  of  attacking  this  problem  is  to  ascertain  the  value 
of  the  stumpage  on  a  liberal  basis.  Good  stumpage  is  sold  at  $2  in 
this  district.  Assume  that  200  million  feet  are  destroyed,  that  this 
timber  would  have  formed  a  uniform  part  of  the  cut  during  the  20 
years.  Then  its  present  value  is  as  follows  : 


104  FOREST  VALUATION 

Every  year  10  million  would  have  been  cut,  valued  at  $20,000 ; 

(i.o320  —  i) 

total  present  value :  20,000  —  -  =  $296,000. 

(1.03  —  1)  I.0320- 

In  questions  of  this  kind  there  is  still  some  uncertainty  as  to 
how  far  a  company  or  person  should  be  held  responsible  in  cases  of 
fire.  In  the  city  the  owner  of  a  burning  building  is  generally  not 
held  liable  for  harm  which  comes  to  other  properties  from  the  burn- 
ing of  his.  In  any  case  the  public  arid  both  parties  to  the  suit  are 
more  or  less  closely  bound  together  and  should  suffer  together. 

This  case  sufficiently  illustrates  efforts  at  determining  damage. 
It  is  evident  that  it  is  chiefly  a  matter  of  accurate  examination  into 
all  the  facts  and  the  establishment  of  a  reasonable  basis  which  is 
needed.  Detail  knowledge  of  the  business  and  honest  dealing  should 
solve  these  problems  outside  the  courts. 


VIII.    TAXATION  OF  FORESTS 

The  subject  of  forest  taxation  is  primarily  one  of  public  policy; 
the  attitude  of  government  toward  the  forest  business.  But  since 
the  basis  of  equitable  taxation  of  forests  must  be  supplied  by  forest 
valuation  a  brief  treatment  of  this  subject  is  necessary. 

a.  Taxation  is  for  public  good,  to  collect  money  for  public 
expenses.     There  are  three  fundamental  principles  apparent  in  all 
taxation  except  punitive  forms  which  have  no  place  here : 

1.  All  people  are  asked  to  share  in  proportion  as  they  are  able 
to  pay. 

2.  Taxation  should  be  no  more  irksome  or  offensive  than  is 
necessary,  indirect  taxation,  revenue,  tariff,  etc. 

3.  Taxation  should  not  interfere  or  injure  useful  or  necessary 
business.    While  rarely  expressed  in  just  this  way,  the  many  modi- 
fications of  the  methods  of  taxation  to  suit  different  kinds  of  busi- 
ness were  based  on  this  principle  fully  as  much  as  on  the  difficulty 
of  finding  a  satisfactory  basis. 

Even  in  the  United  States  we  have  taxes  of  various  kinds :  or- 
dinary property  tax  for  house,  farm,  valuables,  etc. ;  income  tax, 
national,  and  also  for  railways  by  states,  poll  tax  or  head  tax,  "road 
tax"  to  be  worked  out  or  paid  for,  tariff  duties,  internal  revenues, 
licenses  to  do  business,  special  taxes,  like  present  war  tax,  and  other 
forms. 

Taxes  are  gathered  by  United  States  authorities  for  the  na- 
tional government  and  by  local  authorities  for  town,  county  and 
state. 

b.  In  ordinary  taxation  of  real  estate  in  the  United  States  we 
have  to  distinguish  between  assessment  and  rate. 

i.  The  assessment  sets  a  value  on  the  property.  It  usually 
takes  the  ordinary  sale  or  market  value,  it  may  take  the  entire  value 
or  only  a  certain,  more  or  less  uncertain  fraction.  This  latter  con- 
dition is  not  always  fixed  by  law  and  even  where  it  is,  it  is  com- 
monly modified  in  practice  and  gives  the  assessor  a  chance  to  favor 
certain  persons  or  properties.  It  is  clear  that  this  local  agent,  an 
ordinary  elective  officer,  without  special  training,  experience  or  other 
qualities,  can  modify  the  amount  of  taxes  paid  on  any  particular 
property  and  in  this  way  he  becomes  the  most  important  part  in  the 
entire  tax  system. 


106  FOREST  VALUATION 

That  this  is  not  easily  overcome  by  law  is  well  illustrated  in  the 
report  of  the  State  Tax  Commission  of  Michigan  where  it  is  shown 
that  about  one  half  of  the  state,  in  1914,  was  assessed  at  nearly  full 
value,  (ninety-seven  per  cent),  and  the  other  half  at  only  sixty-nine 
per  cent,  in  spite  of  the  law  which  requires  assessment  at  full  cash 
value,  and  in  spite  of  the  efforts  of  past  tax  commissioners.  As 
late  as  1911  the  assessment  for  the  whole  state  was  about  sixty-one 
per  cent  of  the  full  value. 

Assessment  is  not  always  simple.  A  i6o-acre  farm  with  ordi- 
nary buildings  may  make  a  good  net  income  and  yet  sell  for  only 
$50  an  acre  while  a  similar  farm  with  fine  brick  buildings,  etc.,  may 
not  pay  expenses  and  yet  sell  for  $TCO  an  acre.  Fundamentally  the 
owner  of  the  first  farm  is  better  able  to  pay.  In  practice  the  second 
farmer  pays  double  the  taxes. 

A  store  or  factory  doing  poor  business  may  not  be  worth  the 
land  and  buildings,  or  visible  property,  one  doing  a  good  business 
may  be  worth  five  times  the  sale  value  of  the  visible  property.  Of 
two  railways  from  Detroit  to  Chicago  the  shorter  one  is  the  best 
paying  and  most  valuable  but  the  longer  route  cost  more  money  to 
build  and  maintain,  etc. 

2.  The  rate  of  taxation  is  set  to  meet  the  expenses  necessary 
or  supposed  to  be  necessary  by  state,  county  and  town.  The  total 
taxes,  state,  county,  town,  including  road,  school,  etc.,  for  Michigan 
have  been  about  fifteen  to  eighteen  per  thousand  dollars  worth  of 
property.  Of  $16.55  total  taxes  in  1902,  $12.26  were  for  local  taxes, 
town,  school,  roads,  etc.,  $2.41  for  county  and  only  $1.88  for  state. 
Naturally  the  local  taxes  vary  most,  and  vary  from  one  school  dis- 
trict to  another,  even  in  the  same  township.  The  great  range  for 
different  counties  in  the  same  state  is  apparent  from  the  following: 
for  1901  the  average  tax  rate  for  the  different  counties  in  Michigan 
was  as  follows : 

Over  $  50  per  $1000  property  in     I  county 

40-49  5 

30-39  13 

20-29  30 

15-19  18 

10-14  15 

Below  10  dollars  i 

It  is  apparent  that  in  any  county  where  timber  is  assessed  at 
full  value  and  taxed  at  forty  dollars  per  thousand  of  value,  the  inter- 
est and  taxes  eat  up  the  property  every  six  or  ten  years.  Since  this 
rate  is  an  arbitrary  affair  without  limits  and  left  to  local  politicians, 


UNITED  STATES  TAX  RATES 


107 


it  is  quite  common  that  the  tax  rate  and  not  the  tax  assessment  is 
the  more  dreaded  phase  of  taxation.  Good,  old  settled,  rural  dis-' 
tricts  in  southern  Michigan  commonly  fall  below  ten  dollars  per 
thousand  of  property  while  poorly  settled,  new,  districts  are  normally 
high  in  their  tax  rates,  in  fact  one  of  the  most  sparsely  settled  coun- 
ties in  1901  had  an  average  tax  rate  of  over  sixty-three  dollars  per 
thousand  of  property.  It  is  doubtful  if  rural  taxes  should  be  al- 
lowed to  go  much  above  ten  dollars  per  thousand. 

In  this  connection  the  following  table  is  interesting : 

Tax  Rate  Per  Thousand  Dollars  of  Assessed  Valuation, 

according  to  bulletin  109,  Department  of  Commerce  and  Labor, 
1910,  p.  849 : 


1890 

$18.50 

16.40 

14.40 
23.70 


1880 

$18.30 

17.70 

12.70 
20.90 


1870 

$19.80 

18.70 

14.10 
24.00 


1860 
$7-80 
9.70 


11.70 


1002 

Continental    United    States $20.50 

North  Atlantic,   Maine- Penna.. .    18.30 
South  Atlantic,  Delaware- 
Florida    16.00 

North  Central,  Ohio-Wisconsin- 

Kansas-Mirmesota     24.70 

South  Central,  Kentucky-Arkan- 
sas-Alabama-Texas        J7-3O 

Western,  including  Pacific  Coast  25.50 

Ohio     23.80 

Indiana    19.70 

Illinois    5.1.50 

Michigan    16.60 

New    York    22.20 

Pennsylvania    14.90 

Massachusetts     15.80 

Wisconsin    13.60 


The  above  table  indicates  that  Michigan,  in  this,  as  many  other 
matters  is  very  nearly  average  and  also  that  for  the  entire  Union 
fifteen  to  twenty  dollars  per  thousand  is  considered  a  reasonable 
rate.  The  tendency  to  increase  in  rate  may  be  expected  to  give  way 
to  a  tendency  to  decrease  with  about  twelve  dollars  per  thousand  as 
the  proper  minimum  for  the  state  and  about  six  dollars  for  rural 
property.  In  circular  132,  A,  United  States  Department  of  Agri- 
culture, 1913,  this  rate  of  six  dollars  per  thousand,  of  farm  property, 
is  accepted  as  average  for  farm  property  in  the  United  States.  As 


14.30 

16.30 

18.00 

4.10 

19.90 

22.30 

25-50 

17.70 

19.10 

16.80 

20.  IO 

IO.OO 

18.20 

16.40 

16.30 

9.00 

40.90 

31-30 

45.20 

15.70 

16.10 

16.70 

19.90 

10.80 

19.80 

21.30 

24.70 

11.00 

14.00 

17.10 

18.70 

12.10 

14.60 

15.40 

1570 

9.6O 

22.90 

18.70 

16.20 

12.50 

108  FOREST  VALUATION 

pointed  out,  property  is  not  assessed  at  full  value  and  even  in  states 
where  the  law  demands  this  it  is  not  done  consistently.  In  most 
states  the  assessment  is  at  about  2/3  value  for  rural  property  and 
varies  from  twenty-five  to  one  hundred  per  cent  in  city  property 
with  large  amounts  escaping  taxation  altogether. 

c.  When  farm  taxes  were  gathered  as  "tithes,"  or  one-tenth 
of  the  crop,  not  in  money  but  in  grain,  etc.,  the  tax  was  clearly  a 
personal  tax  and  of  the  nature  of  income  tax,  on  gross  income. 

When  this  changed  to  a  fixed  money  tax,  based  on  the  value  of 
the  farm  and  this  latter  based  on  the  fertility  of  the  farm,  it  lost  the 
character  of  a  personal  tax  though  still  of  the  nature  of  a  tax  on  an 
implied  or  estimated  income. 

Today  in  the  United  States  the  farm  or  forest  is  assessed  at  its 
sale  value;  the  tax  books  are  based  on  the  property,  it  is  the  prop- 
erty which  is  taxed  regardless  of  ownership.  If  the  owner  neglects 
to  pay,  it  is  not  the  owner  who  is  looked  up  and  addressed,  but  the 
property  itself  which  is  at  once  taken  charge  of  and  sold  for  taxes, 
etc. 

The  property  tax  as  it  applies  to  real  estate,  farm  and  forest, 
then,  is  no  longer  a  personal  tax,  it  ignores  the  owner  and  condi- 
tion of  ownership,  is  not  concerned  whether  the  owner  is  able  finan- 
cially, or  poor  and  in  debt,  whether  or  not  he  makes  any  income  from 
this  property. 

d.  In  Europe  forests  are  taxed  in  various  ways.    Usually  the 
forest  property  is  so  regulated  that  a  yearly  income  is  secured  and 
the  ordinary  forest  property  resembles  the  farm  and  the  ability  of 
the  owner  to  pay  is  much  more  easily  determined. 

The  three  forms  of  forest  taxation  most  generally  applied  in 
central  Europe  are:  ground  tax;  income  tax;  property  tax. 

1.  The  ground  Tax,  "Grundsteuer,"  or  "Ertragsteuer,"  of  the 
Germans  is  a  tax  on  the  soil,  based  on  its  estimated  income  or  else 
on  an  official  estimate  of  the  productivity,  "Kataster,"  and  is  used 
exactly  like  the  ordinary  tax  on  farm  property  or  real  estate  in  the 
United  States ;  where  the  farm  is  largely  assessed  according  to  the 
crop  it  produces. 

2.  The  property  tax  of  European  states  is  a  regulator  in  cases 
where  the  property  does  not  produce  an  income  in  keeping  with  its 
value.    An  empty  lot  in  the  city  is  only  an  expense  to  the  owner  but 
it  has  a  sale  value.     Similarly  a  farm  in  the  outskirts  of  a  city  may 
be  worth  a  thousand  dollars  an  acre  and  yet  as  a  farm  may  not  make 
as  large  a  net  income  as  another  farm  three  miles  away  and  valued 


INCOME;  TAX  IN  FOREST  109 

at  only  one  hundred  an  acre.  Private  parks,  summer  homes,  etc., 
belong  in  this  class.  In  these  cases  the  sale  value  of  the  property  is 
taken  in  the  assessment. 

3.  Income  tax  is  a  personal  tax  and  takes  a  certain  part,  say 
one-tenth,  of  the  net  income.    The  income  is  taken  as  an  average  of 
three  or  five  years  and  all  expenses  are  deducted.    In  these  expenses 
are  included  also  the  interest  which  the  owner  of  the  property  is 
paying  on  debt.     The  following  case  illustrates : 

Area  of  property,  10,000  acres ; 
Forest  of  spruce,  all  one  site; 
Clear  cut  and  plant,  rotation,  100  years ; 
Yr,  $500,  yearly  cut,  100  acres,  worth  $50,000 ; 
Yearly  expenses,  $1.50  an  acre,  or  $15,000  total; 
Tax  rate,  one-tenth  of  net  income.    The  taxes  are : 
o.ioX  (50,000 — 15,000)  or  $3,500. 

This  amount  is  seven  per  cent  of  the  stumpage  value  of  the 
ripe  timber  cut  during  the  year  so  that  a  yield  tax  of  seven  per  cent 
in  this  typical  case  is  equivalent  to  ten  per  cent  on  net  income. 

If  in  the  above  case  there  was  a  mortgage  of  $200,000  at  4% 
on  the  property  the  $8,000  of  interest  would  be  added  to  the  expenses 
and  the  taxes  reduced  to  $2,700. 

4.  Where  the  forest  is  not  regulated  it  does  not  produce  a 
yearly  income  but  produces  an  income  only  at  long-  intervals,  (inter- 
mittent working  of  Schlich),  as  for  instance  a  single  plantation,  all 
one  age  and  kind  where,  if  we  neglect  thinnings,  no  income  is  se- 
cured from  time  of  planting  till  the  stand  is  ripe.    In  such  cases  the 
method  of  taxation  by  income  tax  is  not  readily  applicable  and  vari- 
ous modifications  are  employed.     The  simplest  of  these  and  most 
nearly  in  keeping  with  the  principle  of  income  tax  is  the  postponing 
of  payment  until  the  timber  is  ripe  and  then  paying  a  sufficient  sum 
in  keeping  with  the  large  income  at  that  "time. 

In  other  cases  the  value  of  the  intermittent  income  is  calculated 
and  converted  into  a  yearly  income  by  the  formula : 

periodic  income  _  yearly  income 
i.opr — i  i. op — i 

periodic  income 

.  .  yearly  income  = ; .op. 

i. op1— i 

But  this  means  practically  a  return  to  the  ground  tax  system  which 
in  these  cases  no  doubt  deserves  preference. 


I  IO 


FOREST  VALUATION 


5.  The  state  and.  local  taxes  in  Germany  are  not  always  com- 
puted by  the  same  methods,  in  fact  it  is  common  for  state  taxes  to 
be  levied  as  income  tax  and  local  taxes  as  ground  or  property  tax. 

Since  the  state  forests  pay  local  taxes,  corresponding  to  county, 
town,  highway,  etc.,  taxes  with  us,  and  since  these  local  taxes  repre- 
sent probably  not  less  than  seventy-five  per  cent  of  all  taxes  paid,  the 
following  figures  are  of  interest,  doubly  so  because  they  affect  a 
large  proportion  of  all  forests  of  the  several  states. 

Local  taxes  paid  on  the  state  forests  of  Wiirttemberg  on  a  total 
area  of  about  490,000  acres : 


Value 

Local  taxes  paid  by  state. 

of 

forest 
or 

Yearly 

Years. 

net 
income 
capital- 
ized 
at  10%. 

net 
income 
per 
acre. 

Total 
$1000. 

Per 
acre. 

$ 

Tax 

on 

IOOO 

property. 

Tax 

as  %  of 
net 
income. 

Tax 

as% 
of 
stump- 
age. 

$per 

$ 

% 

acre. 

1880-89 

26 

$2.69 

80.9 

.16 

6.10 

6 

4.2 

1890-99 

38 

3-86 

105 

.21 

5-50 

5-4 

4-3 

1900 

5<J 

5-07 

117 

•23 

4.60 

4-5 

3-7 

1901 

54 

5-41 

119  . 

.24 

4-45 

4-4 

3-4 

1902 

47 

4-73 

126 

•25 

5-30 

5-2 

4.1 

1903 

51 

5.10 

128 

.26 

5-10 

5.1 

3-9 

1904 

57 

5-79 

105 

.21 

3.60 

3-6 

2.9 

1905 

61 

6.10 

167 

•34 

5-55 

5-6 

4.2 

1906 

67 

6.78 

178 

•36 

5-35 

5-3 

4-i 

1907 

74 

7-47 

188 

.38 

5.10 

5-1 

4-1 

1908 

65 

6.50 

200 

.41 

6.30 

6-3 

4-9 

Assuming  these  local  taxes  to  be  seventy-five  per  cent  of  total 
taxes  the  forests  of  Wiirttemberg  were  taxed  in  1908  on  a  basis  of 
about  $8.40  per  $1,000;  or  8.4  of  net  income,  or  6.5  stumpage  tax, 
or  54  cents  an  acre.  The  following  figures  represent  the  same  con- 
dition for  the  state  forests  of  Baden  for  the  year  1002,  arranged  by 
the  political  districts: 


TAX  RATES  IN  EUROPE  1 1  I 

Local  taxes  paid  by  the  state  forests  of  Baden  in  1002 : 


Value 

of 

Local  Taxes. 

District. 

Area 
of 
forests, 

1000 

acres. 

Net 
yearly 
income 
per 
acre. 

forest 
on 
basis 
of 
net 
income 

Tax  on 

$1000 

prop- 
erty. 

Tax 

as% 
of 
net 
income. 

Tax 

as% 
of 
stump- 
age. 

Total 

IOOO. 

Per 
acre. 

and 

10%. 

i 

13 

$ 
8.48 

$ 
84 

$ 

3-5 

$ 
.27 

$ 
3.20 

% 
3-2 

2.7 

2 

4-5 

3-52 

35 

.8 

.18 

5-10 

5-1 

4. 

3 

no 

5.98 

59 

32.5 

.29 

4.90 

4-9 

3-5 

4 

50 

5-92 

59 

23-7 

•47 

8.00 

8. 

6.1 

5 

46 

6.19 

61 

4-5 

.09 

1.48 

1.4 

2.1 

6 

8 

4-13 

4i 

3-2 

.40 

9.80 

9.8 

7- 

7 

14 

2.04 

20 

3-2 

.22 

11.00 

ii. 

7- 

Entire 
state 

248 

5.78 

57 

73 

.29 

5.10 

5-1 

4-4 

The  great  variation  in  the  local  taxation  as  it  appears  in  this 
table  is,  no  doubt,  due  to  the  fact  that  so  many  villages  and  towns 
in  parts  of  Baden  have  large  communal  properties  which  relieve 
local  taxation  very  materially. 

On  previous  assumption  of  local  taxes  representing  seventy- 
five  "per  cent  of  total  taxes  the  Baden  forests  were  taxed  in  1902 
about  thirty-eight  cents  an  acre ;  six  dollars  and  eighty  cents  per 
thousand  dollars  worth  of  property ;  six  and  eight-tenths  per  cent  of 
net  income ;  or  five  and  eight-tenths  per  cent  of  stumpage  cut  per 
year. 

In  Prussia  with  about  6,540,000  acres  of  state  forest  the  local 
taxes  for  many  years  varied  between  three  and  a  half  and  four  and 
a  half  per  cent  of  total  expenses.  Taking  the  year  1892-93  as  basis 
of  income  and  expenses,  the  following  results : 

Total  income  per  acre $  2.66 

Total  expenses  per  acre i  •  38 

Net  income  per  acre 1 . 27 

Value  of  forest  per  acre  on  10%  basis 12.70 

Local  taxes  at  4%   of  expenses  per  acre:   5.2  cents, 

Local  taxes  per  $1000  property 4.20 

As  per  cent  of  net  income  4-2% 

As  per  cent  of  stumpage 2-3% 


112  FOREST  VALUATION 

Assuming  again  the  local  taxes  to  be  seventy-five  per  cent  of 
total  taxes  these  forests  appear  taxed  at  about  seven  cents  per  acre ; 
or  five  dollars  and  sixty  cents  per  thousand ;  five  and  six-tenths  of 
net  income,  or  three  per  cent  of  value  of  stumpage. 

6.  The  general  tendency  in  forest  taxation  in  Europe  is 
toward  some  form  of  income  tax  but  it  is  doubtful  if  ground  tax 
and  property  tax  will  ever  be  entirely  dispensed  with.  An  important 
and  interesting  fact  is  that  forestry  as  a  business  is  not  only  possi- 
ble but  thrives  under  a  variety  of  methods  of  taxation  and  that  in 
the  best  forest  districts,  Wiirttemberg,  Saxony  and  Baden,  the  old- 
est form  of  ground  tax  is  still  employed. 

This  clearly  proves  that  it  is  not  so  much  a  matter  of  method 
of  taxation  as  it  is  an  understanding  of  forestry  as  a  business  and 
a  sense  of  justice  which  is  needed,  here,  as  in  many  other  lines  of 
taxation.  The  application  of  some  one  simple  method  by  one  au- 
thority, as  is  done  today  in  the  United  States  for  farm  property, 
would  certainly  be  preferable  to  the  irregular  variety  of  taxation, 
in  method,  rate  and  authority  of  most  European  countries. 

e.     Forest  taxation  in  the  United  States. 

1.  Forests  are  taxed  in  all  states  of  the  Union  as  real  estate, 
the  timber  and  the  land,  or  crop  and  land  being  taxed  together.   The 
taxation  is  not  uniform :  in  one  county  the  forest  may  be  assessed 
low  as  wild  land,  in  another  the  timber  is  carefully  estimated  and 
its  value  added.    Non-resident  owners  and  therefore  a  large  part  of 
the  forest  owners  usually  fare  worse  than  residents  of  the  township 
or  county.    A  common  mistake  is  to  assess  stumpage  which  can  not 
possibly  come  into  use  for  years,  as  if  it  were  ready  to  cut  at  once. 
For  instance — a  lumber  company  has  twenty  years'  supply  of  stump- 
age;  its  mill  is  the  most  important  enterprise  in  the  county,  furnishes 
opportunity  for  labor,  market  for  produce  and  a  supply  of  cheap 
building  material.     Stumpage  is  worth  six  dollars  per  M.  feet.    At 
a  recent  revision  an  effort  was  made  to  assess  the  twenty  years  sup- 
ply at  this  rate.    It  was  shown  that  by  doing  so  with  the  prevailing 
tax  rate  of  three  per  cent,  the  taxes  and  interest  would  eat  up  the 
value  of  a  large  part  of  this  stumpage  long  before  the  timber  could 
be  used  at  the  mill. 

The  complaint  usually  is  that  the  present  methods  of  taxation 
force  the  owners  to  cut  and  thereby  discourage  the  holding  of  for- 
ests. 

2.  In  actual  forestry  practice,  the  present  method  of  assessing 
the  stand  at  full  sale  value  and  taxing  it  at  a  rate  of  three  per  cent 
would  prove  prohibitory.     To  illustrate:  a  plantation  of  white  pine 


INFLUENCE;  OF  TAX  RATES  113 

costs  ten  dollars  an  acre  and  is  located  on  land  worth  ten  dollars 
more.  It  is  assessed  at  twenty  dollars  and  pays  taxes  at  three  per 
cent  for  thirty  years.  So  far  the  owner  has  had  no  income  but  has 
paid  sixty  cents  per  year  for  taxes  alone.  This  together  with  inter- 
est at  three  per  cent  makes  thirty  years  holding-  of  the  plantation 
cost  $28.54  for  taxes.  If  now  the  value  of  the  stand 

At  30  years  is     $100 

At  50  years  is     250 

At  70  years  is    400 

and-  if  the  assessment  is  raised,  as  it  should  be  according  to  law  in 
some  states,  to  these  values  at  thirty  and  at  fifty  years  the  case  is 
as  follows : 

Taxes  and  interest  between  30-50  years $  80 

Taxes  and  interest  between  50-70  years 200 

and  the  growth  in  value  of  the  stand  between  fifty  and  seventy  years 
fails  by  as  much  as  fifty  dollars  to  make  good  the  expense  of  taxes. 

In  addition  to  taxes  there  is  a  charge  of  $39.14  between  30  and 
50  and  a  charge  of  $70.68  between  50  and  70  on  the  original  invest- 
ment of  land  and  plantation. 

The  above  case  presents  no  special  peculiarities,  the  rotation  of 
seventy  years  is  below  the  ordinary  and  the  value  of  the  stand  at 
seventy  is  liberal.  It  is  evident  therefore  that  with  present  methods 
of  assessment  and  rates,  forestry,  even  at  such  favorable  conditions 
as  in  the  above  case,  must  be  carried  on  at  a  large  loss. 

The  fundamental  fallacy  of  this  method  lies  in  the  fact  that 
the  same  year's  growth  is  taxed  over  and  over  again,  for  seventy 
years,  in  the  above  case.  This  is  never  done  in  taxation  of  farm 
property. 

3.  From  the  standpoint  of  the  state  or  people  the  following 
is  true :  To  the  state  the  taxes  on  standing  timber  are  only  of  mod- 
erate importance ;  in  the  Lake  states  and  east  of  very  little  import- 
ance. On  the  other  hand  the  secondary  benefit  through  manufac- 
ture of  timber  is  of  great  value  to  the  state.  With  the  counties  this 
varies.  In  well  settled  farm  counties  the  taxes  from  woodlots  are 
unimportant  and  there  is  no  reason  why  woodlots  should  not  be 
treated  like  the  rest  of  the  farm  land,  i.  e.,  the  value  of  the  timber 
left  out  of  consideration.  In  sparsely  settled  forested  counties  the 
taxes  from  timber  are  important  and  there  is  usually  clamor  for 
large  sums  and  also  for  a  steady  income,  to  enable  development. 


114  FOREST  VALUATION 

In  some  localities  this  is  justified,  in  most  places  it  is  not,  for  usually 
the  sawmill,  etc.,  are  worth  more  to  the  counties  than  any  direct 
taxes.  Lack  of  state  control  and  the  unreasonable  insistence  on  high 
local  taxes  have  repeated  the  story  of  the  goose  of  the  golden  egg 
a  great  many  times  in  all  our  forest  districts. 

The  claims  of  the  local  people  are  usually  of  this  order:  the 
forests  were  not  raised  by  their  present  owners  but  given  away  by 
the  people  at  nominal  prices  to  encourage  the  timber  business  and 
general  development.  The  owners  are  not  in  the  forestry  business 
and  have  no  intention  of  perpetuating  the  forest.  There  is  no  reason 
why  a  man  should  not  pay  taxes  en  a  hundred  thousand  dollars 
which  he  invests  in  timber  exactly  as  if  he  had  invested  it  in  other 
property.  The  holding  of  large  areas  of  forest  is  a  form  of  land 
monopoly  and  generally  inimical  to  settlement  and  development. 

f.     Reform  in  forest  taxation  in  the  United  States. 

i.  For  about  forty  years  efforts  have  been  made  to  encourage 
forestry  either  by  modifying  taxation  or  by  actual  bonus.  Among 
the  earliest  of  these  efforts  was  the  Timber  Culture  Act  of  1873, 
giving  United  States  lands  on  condition  of  establishment  of  a  stand 
of  forest  trees.  Since  that  time  different  states  have  enacted  a 
variety  of  laws.  Usually  the  aim  was  to  encourage  planting  of 
woods  in  small  tracts. 

In  some  cases  the  plantation  was  exempt  entirely  or  partially, 
in  others  only  the  land  was  taxed  and  assessed  at  nominal  value,  etc. 
In  most  cases  these  laws,  excepting  the  United  States  Timber  Cul- 
ture Act,  produced  no  results  whatever.  In  the  last  five  years,  Con- 
necticut, Massachusetts,  New  York  and  Pennsylvania  have  enacted 
well  planned  laws. 

In  recent  legislation  the  following  three  essential  points  in  our 
transition  stages  of  forestry  in  the  United  States  are  considered : 

The  requirement  of  the  local  people  of  a  continuous  income  is 
met  by  a  yearly  tax  on  the  land,  either  on  its  sale  value,  or  a  nominal 
value. 

Lack  of  income  from  plantations  and  immature  stands  is  con- 
sidered by  deferring  the  tax  on  the  timber  to  the  time  of  cutting,  i.  e., 
making  it  a  harvest  or  yield  tax. 

The  variable  and  peculiar  condition  of  merchantable  timber  is 
taken  care  of  by  varying  the  amount  of  the  yield  tax. 

In  the  Connecticut  law  of  1913  the  following  provisions  are 
made: 

i.  The  application  of  the  new  tax  law  is  optional  with  the 
owner. 


NEW   TAX   LAWS  115 

2.  Land  worth  twenty-five  dollars  or  more  is  not  considered 
forest  land  and  does  not  come  under  the  provisions  of  the  act. 

3.  An  existing  forest  placed  under  the  ne\v  law  pays  not  over 
ten  per  mill  on  actual  value  of  the  forest  as  a  yearly  tax,  and  when 
the  timber  is  cut  it  pays  a  yield  tax  which  is  varied  as  follows : 

If  cut  in  first  ten  years,  yield  tax.  ..  .  2%  of  stumpage  value 
2nd  3%  of  stumpage  value 

3rd  4%  of  stumpage  value 

4th  5%  of  stumpage  value 

5th  6%  of  stumpage  value 

after  5th  7%  of  stumpage  value 

4.  New  plantations  are  not  exempt,  but  pay: 

a.  Yearly  tax  on  the  assessed  value  of  the  land  alone  at  not 
over  ten  per  mill ; 

b.  Yield  tax  of  ten  per  cent  of  the  stumpage  value  of  the  ma- 
terial removed,  to  be  paid  when  the  timber  is  cut. 

In  the  Pennsylvania  law  of  1913  the  harvest  or  yield  tax  is 
also  set  at  ten  per  cent  of  the  stumpage  value,  the  land  is  assessed 
at  one  dollar  per  acre  and  the  state  pays  the  yearly  land  tax  and  the 
owner  of  forests  is  free  to  avail  himself  of  the  law. 

g.     Basis  of  new  tax  laws. 

1.  The  various  efforts  at  some  reform  in  forest  taxation  clear- 
ly show  a  lack  of  uniformity  in  the  basis  for  such  tax  law.     Even 
with  regard  to  the  land  we  have : 

Lands  worth  over  twenty-five  dollars  excluded: 

Lands  assessed  at  sale  value ; 

Lands  assessed  at  one  dollar,  in  Pennsylvania,  and  assessment 
at  five  dollars  recommended  by  Massachusetts. 

A  reasonable  sale  value  should  be  employed,  and  there  is  no 
reason  why  even  fifty  dollar  land  should  be  excluded.  Efforts  at 
tax  dodging  would  be  taken  care  of  by  the  sale  value  assessment. 

2.  The  greatest  amount  of  uncertainty,  however,  was  involved 
in  finding  a  proper  rate  for  the  yield  tax.     Should  it  be  five  or  ten 
per  cent,  should  it  be  ten  per  cent  of  the  stumpage,  of  logs  at  land- 
ing, at  mill,  etc.? 


Il6  FOREST  VALUATION 

Pennsylvania  and  Connecticut  employed  ten  per  cent  without 
apparently  attempting  to  develop  a  reasonable  basis  or  giving  an 
explanation. 

The  Massachusetts  Commission,  see  Senate  document  number 
426,  1914,  made  an  effort  which  proves  instructive.  Its  premises  are : 

Rotation,  50  years,  also  assumed  by  Connecticut  and  Vermont 
in  recent  acts  (setting  a  general  rotation  is  of  very  doubtful  value 
and  certainly  50  years  will  not  raise  proper  sizes  for  general  mar- 
ket) ; 

Tax  rate,  $17.39  per  $1.000  worth  of  property: 

Yield  at  50  years,  $240;  value  of  land,  $5  per  acre;  interest  rate 
for  total  tax,  8%  ;  for  land  tax.  5%. 

The  plan  is  to  pay  a  yearly  tax  on  the  land  and  pay  a  yield  tax 
at  the  time  of  cutting  the  timber.  The  reasoning  is  this :  the  income 
from  this  property  consists  in  the  timber  cut.  The  tax  on  this  in- 
come or  timber  is  the  tax  for  the  whole  property,  timber  and  land. 

The  land  tax  is  paid  to  furnish  a  yearly  income  for  the  local 
government  but  should  be  deducted  from  the  yield  tax  which  is  the 
principal  tax  which  the  property  should  pay. 

Computation  of  yield  tax  or  principal  tax : 

The  present  value  of  Yr  pays  taxes  every  year  at  rate  of  $17.39 
per  $1,000,  and  this  is  to  be  compounded  at  8%,  so  that  for  $i  of 
Yr  we  have: 


(— |  —yield  tax  for  each  $i  Yr,  or  $0.212. 
I.Oo — I  / 


i.oS50/x  1000  V  i.o8—i/ 

Of  this  21  cents  only  2/3  is  taken,  since  it  is  customary  in  Massa- 
chusetts to  tax  rural  property  on  a  2/3  valuation.  The  yield  tax  then 
is  14  cents  for  each  dollar  of  final  yield  or  thirty-three  dollars  and 
sixty  cents  an  acre,  if  $240  worth  of  timber  is  cut  per  acre. 
The  land  tax  is  computed  as  follows : 

W       \S  ',   _*;Qj?       /  '          3  .  __  \ 

5        1000  \  1.05—1    / 

or  $19.11  an  acre,  which  makes  about  12  cents  per  $i  of  final  yield. 
Again  taking  only  2/3  of  this,  or  8  cents  and  subtracting  this  from 
the  14  cents  yield  tax  leaves  a  final  yield  tax  of  6  cents  per  dollar 
of  stumpage,  to  be  paid  at  the  end  of  the  rotation  or  when  the  tim- 
ber is  cut.  In  this  way  the  commission  decided  that  a  yield  tax  of 
six  per  cent  is  a  proper  tax  to  charge. 


BASIS  OF  TAX  RATES  1 17 

An  attempt  to  use  the  Massachusetts  plan  on  other  rotations 
gives,  even  with  a  uniform  land  price  of  five  dollars  an  acre,  the 
following  yield  tax : 

Rotation   50  years 6% 

75  "         3% 

100  — 10% 

so  that  the  state  would  be  rebating  as  soon  as  reasonable  rotations 
are  employed. 

3.  In  seeking  a  proper  basis  for  any  tax  rate  the  following 
may  be  assumed : 

The  most  important  point  of  all  is  that  the  tax  rate  on  forests 
should  be  no  higher  than  that  on  other  rural  property.  If  farm 
property  generally  pays  less  than  twelve  per  thousand  in  practically 
all  parts  of  the  United  States  then  forest  property  should  pay  the 
same,  but  certainly  not  more.  This  principle  is  recognized  in  the 
Massachusetts  plan. 

Again  if  the  value  of  farm  property  universally  is  judged  by 
the  income  which  it  can  produce  the  same  measure  is  fair  for  forest 
property. 

A  yield  tax  should  be  fair  not  only  for  one  rotation  but  for  all 
reasonable  rotations. 

In  judging  the  value  of  a  farm  or  forest  for  taxation  by  capital- 
izing the  net  income  the  interest  rate  should  be  fairly  high,  since  the 
owner  takes  all  risks  and  the  state  takes  none.  This  also  seems  rec- 
ognized by  the  Massachusetts  commission,  and  it  is  common  practice 
in  valuation  of  real  estate. 

If  a  yield  tax  is  fair  for  one  stand  of  timber  it  is  fair  for  any 
other  stand  regardless  of  methods  and  regulation,  and  the  proper 
rate  may,  therefore,  be  found  by  a  study  of  the  regulated  forest. 

That  a  regulated  forest  property  would  pay  more  taxes,  even 
at  the  same  yield  tax  rate  than  a  property  worked  on  the  intermit- 
tent plan,  is  self-evident. 

The  following  case  brings  out  the  relations  of  property  tax  at 
12  per  1,000  and  the  yield  tax  for  the  stands  of  a  regulated  forest  at 
different  rotations. 

Premises :  Yr  is  taken  at  about  half  the  normal  yield  in  spruce, 
site  II,  as  per  Schwappach, 

Yr  at    50  years    $200 

Yr  at    75  years    400 

Yr  at  zoo  years    600 

land,  $5  per  acre,  p — 10%  to  capitalize  net  income  and  find  income 
value  of  the  property, 


Il8  FOREST  VALUATION 

Current  yearly  expenses  $i  per  acre;  cost  of  planting,  $10  per 
acre. 

Tax  rate,  12  per  1,000  as  being  about  average  for  rural  prop- 
erty in  the  United  States. 

Relation  of  property  tax  at  12  per  1,000  and  yield  tax  in  regu- 
lated forest. 

Rotation,  years.  50  75  100 

Minimum  number  of  acres  in  regulated  forest, 

i.  e.,  r  acres   50  75  100 

Yearly    gross    income    from    r    acres,    neglect 

thinnings    $  200  $  400  $  600 

Yearly  expenses  on  r  acres,  current  and  plant- 
ing      $    60  $    85  $  1 10 

Yearly  net  income  from  r  acres $  140  $  315  $  490 

Value  of  the  r  acres  regulated  forest,  i.  e.,  net 

income  capitalized  at  ten  per  cent $1400  $3150  $4900    . 

Taxes,  as  property  tax  at  rate  of  12  per  1000 

on  r  acres    $     16.80      $    37.80      $    58.80 

Property  tax,  12  per  looo,  per  acre $      0.33      $      0.50      $      0.58 

Property  tax  of  12  per  1000  as  a  per  cent  of 

stumpage  cut,  or  Yr 8.4%  9-4%          9.8% 

Property  tax  of  12  per  1000  as  a  per  cent  of 

net  income   12%  12%  12% 

It  is  evident  from  the  above  that. a  twelve  per  mill  tax  on  the 
true  value  of  a  regulated  forest  corresponds  closely  to  a  yield  tax 
of  nine  or  ten  per  cent  of  the  stumpage  value  of  the  timber. 

The  introduction  of  the  land  tax  disturbs  the  simplicity  and 
even  the  justice  of  the  yield  tax  method  since  land  values  differ  and 
this  difference  is  not  always  made  up  by  the  difference  in  final  yield. 
On  lands  where  the  timber  grows  slowly  and  requires  about  one 
hundred  years  to  reach  marketable  size  the  yearly  land  tax  on  five 
dollar  land  even  at  twelve  per  mill  and  compounded  at  as  low  as 
three  per  cent  reaches  the  formidable  sum  of  over  thirty-six  dollars 
an  acre,  a  sum  which  would  seriously  discourage  the  planting  of 
bare  lands  and  frequently  exceed  the  ten  per  cent  yield  tax.  For 
some  time  to  come  and  only  as  an  expedient  to  bring  about  some 
tolerable  reform  the  land  tax  may  be  necessary,  but  a  tax  rate  not 
to  exceed  ten  per  mill  should  then  be  employed.  Cases  like  parks 
and  costly  estates  in  the  vicinity  of  cities  should  receive  special  treat- 
ment and  be  taxed  by  the  ordinary  tax  method. 


FUTURE;  IN  FOREST  TAXATION  119 

Of  late  the  application  of  the  single  tax  has  strongly  been  ad- 
vocated for  forests  as  well  as  other  real  property.  The  single  tax 
is  well  suited  to  forestry;  it  would  stimulate  the  accumulation  of  a 
good  growing  stock  and  the  making  of  improvements,  roads,  proper 
division,  etc.,  and  so  put  a  premium  on  good  forestry.  The  action 
of  the  single  tax  in  forestry  is  exactly  the  same  as  in  farming,  where 
it  stimulates  building  and  keeping  of  plenty  live  stock,  while  the 
present  form,  the  property  tax,  in  a  way  penalizes  the  good  farmer 
with  fine  buildings  and  plenty  of  stock  and  machinery.  But  in  no 
case  should  the  crop,  or  timber  and  land  be  taxed  together,  as  has 
at  times  been  advocated  by  single  taxers.  For  the  existing  virgin 
forest  where  the  owner  merely  holds  a  stored  mass  of  merchantable 
timber  and  is  in  no  way  practicing  forestry  and  wrhere  the  public  is 
determined  to  make  the  owner  divide  the  goods,  practically  given 
away  by  the  people,  there  is  nothing  for  it  but  to  devise  some  com- 
promise. Here  the  simple  property  tax  as  now  applied,  or  a  com- 
bination as  is  represented  in  the  Connecticut  law  is  probably  as  good 
as  any  other. 

h.     Future  in  forest  taxation. 

i.  A  yield  tax  is  inconvenient.  The  owner  of  a  small  forest 
cutting  a  few  poles  or  a  few  cords  of  wood  finds  it  bothersome  to 
record  and  report.  This  leads  to  exemption  for  domestic  use,  as  is 
done  in  the  Connecticut  law.  But  it  is  hard  to  set  limits  in  these 
exemptions,  they  lead  to  confusion  and  bad  practice.  With  large 
owners  it  becomes  necessary  to  take  the  word  of  the  owner,  it  pries 
into  his  affairs  and  has  all  the  objections  commonly  claimed  for  in- 
come taxes.  The  local  tax  official  has  added  a  great  deal  to  his 
labor  and  where  the  matter  is  left  optional  it  involves  inspection  of 
state  foresters  who  lack  help,  money  and  experience. 

For  a  regulated  forest  property  there  is  no  occasion  to  use  a 
yield  tax ;  it  can  be  assessed  as  easily  as  a  farm  and  taxed  in  exactly 
the  same  way. 

For  isolated  tracts,  not  really  managed  as  forest  it  may  bridge 
over,  but  is  not  satisfactory  enough  to  recommend  for  permanent 
practice.  To  receive  a  yield  tax  once  in  eighty  years  introduces  too 
many  chances  for  cheating  the  buyer  of  such  property  and  the  com- 
munity. 

For  a  beginning  the  yield  tax  is  to  be  recommended  to  get  away 
from  the  present  methods,  but  the  tax  collecting  practice  in  rural 
properties  will  work  for  a  return  to  the  property  tax,  properly  regu- 
lated by  computations  based  on  actual  income. 


[20  FOREST  VALUATION 

2.  The  income  tax  has  been  recommended  for  forest  taxation, 
it  is  used  abroad,  it  usually  takes  about  ten  per  cent  of  net  income, 
it  is  simple  in  practice,  tends  to  a  form  resembling  closely  the  ordi- 
nary property  tax  now  in  use.    The  ten  per  cent  basis  is  arbitrary, 
whether  a  remnant  of  the  old  "tithe"  or  a  gradual  adaptation  of 
public  expense  to  personal  income,  yet  it  is  generally  agreed  upon 
as  common  and  fair. 

How  a  ten  per  cent  income  tax  compares  to  our  ordinary  twelve 
per  mill  property  tax  is  shown  by  the  following  figures,  the  basis 
taken  from  circular  132,  A,  1913,  United  States  Department  of 
Agriculture. 

For  the  average  farm  of  the  United  States  the  total  value  is 
$6,343,  the  total  income  $980  and  the  net  income  is  given  at  $538. 
An  income  tax  of  ten  per  cent  on  $538  or  $53  is  equivalent  to  $8.30 
per  $1,000  of  property  and  shows  that  ten  per  cent  of  net  income 
is  only  about  2/3  of  the  ordinary  12  per  1,000  rate  of  taxation  of 
rural  property,  where  this  is  assessed  at  full  value.  Apparently  this 
was  felt  by  rural  tax  officials  and  the  assessment  was  adjusted  to 
make  the  rate  reasonable,  i.  e.,  the  custom  of  taking  rural  property 
at  2/3  value  brings  the  common,  nominal  twelve  per  mill  to  an 
eight  per  mill  on  full  value,  or  close  to  a  ten  per  cent  on  net  income 
as  above  computed. 

3.  From  the  above  it  follows  that  a  ten  per  cent  yield  tax 
which  is  really  ten  per  cent  on  the  gross  income  is  somewhat  too 
high ;  that  about  eight  per  cent  of  the  stumpage  is  more  nearly  right 
and  that  the  addition  of  a  land  tax  is  entirely  unfair.     From  this 
standpoint  the  Pennsylvania  law  requiring  only  the  ten  per  cent 
yield  tax  is  fairest;  the  Massachusetts  law  charging  six  per  cent 
on  yield  and  a  land  tax  on  flat  rate  assessment  comes  next,  but  does 
not  work  well  for  rotations  above  fifty  years,  and  that  the  Connecti- 
cut law  still  demands  an  amount  of  tax  much  greater  than  is  paid 
by  the  average  farmer. 

4.  Taxation  and  protection  more  than  all  other  factors  com- 
bined decide  whether  forestry  can  and  will  be  practiced  by  private 
owners.    The  present  methods  lead  to  confiscation ;  the  recent  laws 
are  a  good  beginning  but  they  still  demand  more  than  is  fair  and 
also  lack  in  convenience  and  simplicity  of  application. 

From  the  standpoint  of  the  state  it  would  be  of  great  value 
in  all  forested  districts  to  pass  some  simple  laws,  applicable  to  all 
forests  and  framed  somewhat  along  the  lines  of  the  Connecticut 
law,  to  provide: 

a.  Taxation  of  all  woodlots  as  parts  of  occupied  farms,  on  a 
basis  of  simple  assessment  of  the  land,  leaving  out  of  consideration 


SUGGESTIONS  IN  TAXATION  I2i 

the  growing  stock  or  crop,  exactly  as  is  done  in  case  of  wheatlands, 
meadows,  etc. 

b.  Exemption  of  forest  plantations  for  twenty-five  years  and 
then  taxation  on  a  land  and  yield  tax,  but  limiting  the  tax  rate  to 
five  per  mill  and  the  yield  tax  to  six  per  cent. 

c.  Taxation  of  existing  forests,  not  parts  of  farms,  on  a  land 
tax  at  five  per  mill  and  a  progressive  yield  tax  with  a  limit  of  six 
per  cent. 

d.  Taxation  of  regulated  forests  on  the  property  tax  plan,  ex- 
actly like  the  farm,  but  the  value  of  the  forest  to  be  the  income 
value  on  a  basis  of  net  income  capitalized  at  ten  per  cent. 

Or  else:  taxation  of  these  forest  properties  by  levy  of  income 
tax  taking  ten  per  cent  of  the  net  income ;  or  as  a  third  alternative, 
a  simple  yield  tax  of  eight  per  cent. 

e.  Providing  a  state  control  which  makes  it  impossible   for 
local  politicians  to  interpret  and  execute  tax  laws  to  suit  their  in- 
terests. 


IX.    FIRE  INSURANCE  IN  FORESTY 


The  timber  or  growing-  stock  in  the  forest  is  liable  to  destruc- 
tion  by  fire  at  any J:ime  of  its  existence.  The  danger  J.s_greater  for 
conifers  than  hardwoods,  greater  for  stands  from  ten  to  thirty 
years  old  than  for  plantations  or  older  timber;  varies  with  the  cli- 
mate, soil,  topography,  and  may  be  reduced  greatly  by  proper  im- 
provenjents  and  protection.  Since  the  timber  or  growing  stock  com- 
monly makes  up  seveniyrfive.j>er.  ce_nt  or  more  of  the  value  of  the 
forest  property,  fire  danger  is  serious. 

For  the  owner  of  a  small  forest,  from  forty  to  one  hundred 
acres,  who  may  lose  in  one  fire  the  greater  part  of  all  he  owns,  this 
is  no  doubt  true.  Generally  the  danger  is  overrated.  The  burning 
of  a  few  plantations  on  a  large  forest  property  is  not  a  serious  mat- 
ter ;  they  must  be  replaced  and  this  adds  to  the  current  expense  but 
it  does  not  affect  the  regular  income  for  years  to  come.  In  stands 
over  fifty  years  old,  the  fire-injured  or  fire-killed  timber  is  not  a 
total  loss,  in  fact,  it  may  be  utilized  often  up  to  eighty  or  ninety  per 
cent  of  its  full  value.  Here  the  fire  may  disturb  the  plans  and  or- 
derly business  of  the  forest  but  does  not  cause  a  serious  loss.  In 
wild  woods  the  case  has  been  different.  In  the  United  States  fires 
have  done  enormous  damage  and  even  today  are  the  greatest  factor 
preventing  action  in  forestry.  According  to  the  report  of  the  Na- 
tional Conservation  Commission  of1 1909,  the  fire  losses  in  the  United 
States  may  be  estimated  at  about  fifty  million  dollars  per  year  for 
merchantable  timber  alone.  To  this  the  report  adds  a  much  larger 
sum  for  destruction  of  stuff  below  merchantable  size  and -usually 
a  total  loss.  Leaving  out  the  latter,  yearly  fire  losses  of  merchant- 
able stuff  for  the  last  fifty  years  in  the  United  States  have  been  at 
least  ten  cents  per  acre  of  forest  area,  and  if  the  average  value  of 
forest  is  twenty  dollars  an  acre,  the  loss  amounts  to  five  dollars  per 
thousand  dollars  worth  of  forest,  or  about  seventy  per  cent  of  what 
good  forests  should  pay  in  taxes. 

The  difficulty  here  has  been  a  lack_oL^rgtecjiDJi_and  lack  of 
market  and  roads  to  enable  immediate  use  of  the  stuff  injured  or 
killed.  It  has  been  the  rule  rather  than  the  exception  that  timber 
killed  byjires  in  the  United  States  has  been  a  total  loss. 

This  is  all  changing  now  and  will  change  a  great  deal  more  even 
in  the  near  future.  It  may  be  expected  that  in  fifty  years  conditions 


FIRES  IN  EUROPE: 


123 


in  the  United  States  except  perhaps  in  the  high  mountain  country 
of  the  west,  will  resemble  those  of  Europe. 

Here  the  fire  danger  is  no  longer  considered  a  serious  difficulty 
in  forestry  and  all  large  owners,  state  and  private,  do  not  even  feel 
the  necessity  of  fire  insurance.  The  following  figures  will  illustrate : 

DAMAGE  FROM  FOREST  FIRES  :* 


Prussia. 

Bavaria 

Austria 

All 
forests. 
1881-1894 

State 
forests. 
1881-1912 

state 
forests. 
1877-1902 

not 
Hungary. 
1881-1895 

Total  area  of  forest,  million  acres.  .. 

20.4 

6.2 

2.07 

24.27 

Total  gross'  income,  million  dollars.  . 

50$ 

15-5 

6 

30$ 

Net  income  per  acre,  approximate  $. 

1.25$ 

1-25 

2 

0.30$ 

Value  of  forests  on  basis  of  3%  and 

net  income,  million  dollars  

810 

250 

120 

24O 

Damage  from  forest  fires  $1000  

93 

4 

ACfft* 

35 

For  each  100,000  acres  of  forest  the 

fires  burned  over    acres 

25 

21 

10 

I/* 

For  every  $1000  gross  income  fire 

*"j 

**ff 

damage  is  in  dollars 

I   QO 

.66 

1.16 

For  every  million  dollars  worth  of 

j.  •  y^ 

forest  damage  is  $.  .       

117 

, 

•3? 

17? 

Average  number  of  fires  per  year.  .  . 

A  A  / 

388 

26 

OO 

91 

*o/ 

Average  area  burned  over  each  year, 

acres 

•4955 

1500 

200 

3420 

In  the  statistical  works  for  Wiirttemberg  and  Baden  the  damage 
by  forest  fires  is  not  even  mentioned.  While  it  is  evident  from  the 
foregoing  that  large  f^restjDwners  have  little  reason  to  seek  insur- 
ance, the  case  is  different  for  the  great  number  of  small  owners. 
For  this  reason  forest^fire  insurance  was  discussed  and  planned  as 
early  as  1877  by  Burckhardt  and  the  matter  agitated  from  that  time 
tcTthis. 

Insurance  by  the  state,  by  cooperation  of  forest  owners  and  by 
commercial  concerns,  all  have  been  discussed. 

*  See  Endres  Forst  Politik,  also  Forstliche  Verhaltnisse  Preussens 
Wurttem'burg,  etc. 

±  May  be  a  little  high  since  it  is  based  on  income  in  state  forests  and 
iveraged  for  a  number  of  years. 


124  FORF.ST  VALUATION 

So  far  only  commercial  organizations  have  worked  extensively 
in  this  field.  Of  these  a  department  of  the  Gladbacher  jfire  insurance 
company,  starting  in  1895  is  the  oldest  and  most  important.  In 
1903  this  company  had  more  than  300,000  acres  of  forest  covered 
by  insurance,  mostly  in  the  densely  settled  Rhine  province  where 
the  forest  is  in  small  tracts.  The  average  rate  has  been  about  $1.80 
perJjSipocLof  property. 

Since  then  the  Bayerische  Hypoteken  und  Wechselbank,  the 
Provincial  Fire  Insurance  Institute  of  the  Rheinprovinz  and  others 
have  taken  up  this  work.  The^rates  usually  run  from  one  to  five 
dollars  per  thousand-  dollars  worth  of  property. 

Usually  it  is  demanded  that  the  insurance  continue  for  at  least 
ten  years,  that  the  owner  insure  all  his  holdings  in  one  company, 
and  that  he  give  to  his  property  such  protection  as  is  customary  in 
the  district,  this  point  being  stipulated  rather  in  detail.  The  rate 
of  premium  varies  with  the  kind  of  timber  and  age,  formerly  the 
rates  increased  with  age  up  to  thirty  years,  this  appears  to  have  been 
given  up  and  the  rate^  starts  with  a  maximum  and  decreases. 

Regular  published  tables  of  yield  and  methods  of  assessing 
damage  are  provided,  the  cost^ and  sale  value  of  the  stand  prevail, 
the  expectation  value  is  permissible  only  under  certain  exceptional 
conditions,  the  payment  is  to  cover  only  actual  damage,  any  income 
from  material  salvaged  is  deducted,  the  interest  rate  for  any  calcu- 
lation of  values  is  three  _per  cent. 

The  following  figures  f rom,  Vorster,  director  of  the  Provincial 
Fire 'insurance  Institute  of  the  Rheinprovinz,  published  in  Zeit- 
schrift  fur  Forst  und  Jagdwesen,  1908,  p.  797,  etc.,  will  illustrate 
what  is  today  good  forest  fire  insurance  as  to  rates,  and  change  in 
these. 

v   j     r  »•    u      •  Premium  per  $1000 

Kind  of  timber  insured.  ,  * 

of  property, 

1.  Pure  'hardwoods,  coppice  or  timber $0.25 —  .80 

2.  Mixed  'hardwoods  and  conifers  in  timber  forest 60 — 1 . 50 

3.  Coppice  mixed  with  conifers   90 — 3 .00 

4.  Pure  conifers: 

Up  to     8  years  old 3.00 — 4.00 

8-15  2.50—4.00 

15-40 i .  50— 2  .co 

over  40  50 — 1.50 

The  following  illustrates  how  a  small  forest  of  pine,  site  IV, 
of  Schwappach,  properly  regulated,  with  present  prices  for  timber, 
fares  in  this  insurance.  Figures  of  the  Rhenish  Institute  are  com- 
pared with  those  of  the  Gladbach  Fire  Insurance  company. 


FIRE:  INSURANCE)  IN  EUROPE; 


125 


For  simplicity,  the  lower  rates  only  are  here  considered  for  both 

"»a  TTIP>C 


companies. 
Cost  < 
acres,  rotation  60  years. 


panics. 

Cost  of  insurance  for  a  regulated  forest  of  pine,  site  IV,  60 


Rhein  Province 

Glad-bach 

Institute. 

Insurance  Co. 

Area. 
Acres. 

Age  of 
Stand. 
Years. 

Value  of 
Stand  per 
Acre  $. 

Premium. 

Premium. 

Rate  per 

$1000. 

Cost  for 
10 
Acres  $. 

Rate  per 
$1000. 

Cost  for 

10 

Acres  $. 

10 

10 

28 

2.50 

.70 

4 

I.  12- 

10 

20 

52 

1.50 

.78 

3-40 

1.76 

10 

30 

9i 

1.50 

1-37 

2.80 

2.56 

10 

40 

133 

i,5o 

2.OO 

2.  2O 

2-93 

10 

50 

165 

.50 

.82 

1.50 

2.48 

10 

60 

197 

•  50 

•98 

1.  00 

1.97 

Total  6.67 

Total  12.84 

Per  acre     .11                                          .21 

Per  $1000  worth  of  woods  i.oo 


1.94 


Assuming  the  yearly  gross  income  from  this  sixty  acres  to  be 
$225,  Yr  +  Tq,  and  the  total  expense  c  -f  e,  $75,  the  insurance 
would  take  4.4%  in  one,  or  8.5%  in  the  other,  of  the  net  income  of 
this  forest.  From  each  $1,000  of  gross  income  this  insurance  takes 
$30  in  one,  $57  in  the  other  company.  Comparing  this  to  the  actual 
yearly  losses  in  Prussia,  $1.90,  and  Bavaria  $0.66,  as  seen  in  the 
foregoing  table,  it  is  easy  to  see  why  the  state  forests  are  not  insured. 

So  far  the  forest  fire  insurance  has  not  been  a  success,  the  com- 
panies have  not  made  any  money  in  this  line  of  insurance  and  the 
proportion  of  forest  insured  is  still  insignificant.  Compulsory  jstate 
insurance  would  no  doubt  readily  solye  this^rjroblem  and  reduce  the 
rate  to  nearly  the  actual  average  loss  and  so  reduce  it  to  less  than 
twenty  per  cent  of  the  present  rates. 

In  this  connection  the  comparison  of  cost  of  insurance  and  cost 
of  good  fire  protection  is  interesting.:  For  a  regulated  forest  of  pine 
with  a  rotation  of  only  sixty  years  the  lowest  premium  is  eleven 
cents  per  acre  for  a  hundred  year  rotation  of  the  same  kind  of 
woods,  pine,  it  amounts  to  twenty-seven  cents.  But  with  any  large 
property  and  any  kind  of  system  of  protection  tenjcents  an  acre  goes 
a  long  way  toward  preventing  fire  entirely  and  certainly  can  well 
reduce  the  damage  to  the  insignificant  minimum  now  secured  in 


126  FOREST  VALUATION 

Germany.  In  the  national  forests  an  expenditure  of  only  about 
t\vo  cents  an  acre  has  reduced  fire  losses  from  an  estimated  ten  cents 
per  acre  to  less  than  one  cent  per  acre.  By  an  expenditure  of  ten 
cents  an  acre  it  is  to  be  expected  that  this  loss  will  be  reduced  still 
further,  and  what  is  more  important,  this  protection  will  protect 
with  a  certainty  regardless  of  conditions,  and  so  prevent  any  of  the 
great  forest  fires  which  from  time  to  time  have  completely  devas- 
tated many  thousands  of  acres  in  a  single  season. 

So  far  forest  fire  insurance  has  not  really  been  tried  in  the 
United  States.  All  financial  concerns,  including  insurance  com- 
panies have  been  afraid  of  forest  properties ;  some  of  the  reasons 
for  this  attitude  are  found  in  the  following  conditions : 

The  values  are  badly  distributed  and  scattered  in  a  forest ;  there 
is  a  large  area  for  a  relatively  small  amount  of  money.  This  is  less 
true  in  the  well-cared  for  forest  with  good  market  than  with  the 
wild  woods ;  and  it  is  less  true  of  the  heavy  stands  of  timber  in  the 
Pacific  coast  states,  but  generally  the  fact  remains.  In  the  city,, 
property  on  one  acre  is  worth  many  thousands,  in^the  forests  of 
the  eastern  half  of  the  United  States  it  is  worth  about  twenty  dollars. 

The  value  of  wild  woods  is  hard  to  ascertain  with  any  degree 
of  accuracy.  The  insurance  company's  agent  can  not  simply  inspect 
and  verify;  it  takes  a  regular  cruise  and  involves  expense. 

The  amount  of  damage  by  a  forest  fire  is  very  hard  to  ascertain. 
A  lot  of  hardwood  timber  run  over  by  fire  may  all  leaf  out  and  ap- 
pear practically  uninjured  and  yet  half  the  stuff  may  die  and  start 
to  decay  before  five  years  are  past.  Two  estimators  would  often 
fail  to  agree  with  regard  to  the  same  tree  before  them. 

Much  of  our  timber  is  owned  in  separated  and  often^videjv 
scattered  bodies. 

The  owners  of  timber  are  only  holding  stumpage;  it  is  a  spec- 
ulative affair,  and  does  not  inspire  confidence.  The  owners  do  not 
practice  forestry,  the  forest  is  left  without  improvements,  roads, 
etc.,  and  there  is  no  real  care  and  protection. 

The  community,  state  and  county.  do_jj.othjng,  as  yet,  to_niake 
forest  property  reasonably  secure. 

Public  opinion  and  habit  has  no  regard  for  forest  property  and 
is  quite  generally  inimical  to  the  owners  of  forests.  This  attitude 
finds  expression  in  the  behavior  of  young  and  old  in  the  forest,  in 
legislation  and  in  the  enforcement  of  law. 

What  the  future  will  bring  is  doubtful.  For  large  owners  of 
forest,  who  practice  real  forestry,  there  is  no  object  in  insuring,  as 


FUTURE;  IN  INSURANCE;  127 

is  evident  from  the  experience  on  the  national  forests  today.  For 
the  small  holding,  especially  the  wqqdlot  on  the  farm,  insurance 
would  be  beneficial  and  may  even  become  necessary  if  these  valuable 
woods  are  to  be  preserve'd.  For  commercial  companies  these  wood- 
lots  are  not  inviting  as  objects  to  insure,  the  difficulties  in  appraisal 
of  damage  alone  being  sufficient  to  discourage  any  company.  It 
will  require  mutual  insurance  as  now  exists  in  many  counties,  or 
state  insurance  will  have  to  supply  security. 


X.    THE  RIGHT  USE  OF  LAND 


FORESTRY  VS.  AGRICULTURE  AND  RANGE. 

a.  Nature  of  land.    Since  the  area  of  land  can  not  be  increased 
and  since  land  can  not  be  moved  from  place  to  place,  the  occupancy 
of  land,  as  by  a  farmer,  is  monopolistic,  and  the  right  use  of  the 
land  is  important,  in  fact,  fundamental  to  the  welfare  of  any  people. 
That  a  farmer  should  have  a  duty,  not  only  to  himself,  but  to  the 
people  or  state,  and  that  the  state  authorities  have  a  duty  in  seeing" 
that  the  land  of  the  state  is  put  to  its  best  use  for  present  and  future, 
are  modern  conceptions,  rapidly  developing  and  becoming  influential 
in  public  economy.    Even  in  the  past,  the  state  felt  justified  in  taxing 
the  shiftless  owner  of  a  good  piece  of  land,  farm  or  city  lot,  not  in 
keeping  with  what  it  produced  but  according  to  what  it  should  pro- 
duce.  Today  all  civilized  states  are  spending  money  to  devise  ways 
and  means  of  making  the  land  more  productive.     In  this  effort  to 
maintain  and  better  the  land  it  is  of  as  much  importance  to  select 
the  right  crop  as  it  is  to  give  the  proper  care,  and  it  is  here  where 
the  choice  between  forest  and  field  crop  asserts  itself. 

b.  Lands  may  roughly  be  divided  into :   agricultural,  forest, 
range  and  waste  lands ;  but  the  lines  between  these  four  classes  are 
rarely  very  sharp. 

On  the  agricultural  lands,  including  the  garden  and  truck  lands, 
the  crop  is  to  furnish  food  for  people  or  animals.  The  forest  crop, 
on  the  other  hand,  serves  two  very  distinct  purposes ;  it  may  merely 
maintain  a  necessary  cover  on  mountain  lands  and  be  useful  as  a 
protective  forest,  or  it  may  serve  solely  to  produce  timber  and  other 
products.  The  importance  of  the  forest  as  protective  cover  is  so 
great  and  has  of  late  been  so  well  recognized  by  the  governments 
of  civilized  countries  that  Martin  in  his  Statik  classifies  lands  into 
those  used  to  raise  products  and  those  requiring  a  protective  cover. 

In  the  following  paragraphs  the  protective  forest  is  considered 
as  occupying  absolute  forest  soil. 

c.  The  factors  which  determine  or  limit  the  use  of  land 
are  chiefly:  climate,   (temperature  and  moisture,)   soil,  topography 
and  population.     In  mountain  countries  small  patches  of  valley  or 
bench  land  may  be  excellent  farm  land  and  yet  not  desirable  for  this 


WHAT    DETERMINES    USE    OE    LAND  1 29 

use  because  of  their  location  and  size,  a  condition  which  applies, 
however,  only  to  a  very  small  per  cent  of  our  lands. 

i.  Climate  is  invariably  the  principal  factor.  More  than  half 
of  N.  America  and  Asia  is  too  cold  for  agriculture;  more  than  35% 
of  North  America,  more  than  sixty  per  cent  of  Asia  and  Africa, 
and  more  than  eighty  per  cent  of  Australia  are  too  dry  for  farming. 

About  forty  degrees  Fahrenheit  average  yearly  temperature 
limits  good  farming;  about  30° F.  ends  the  useful  forest,  except  pro- 
tective woods.  In  the  United  States  about  twenty-five  inches  of 
rainfall  for  the  year  limits  the  natural  forest ;  about  fifteen  inches 
sets  a  limit  to  dry  farming  or  farming  without  irrigation ;  at  ten 
inches  of  rainfall  the  prairie  changes  to  desert. 

In  countries  with  an  average  yearly  temperature  less  than  fifty 
degrees  Fahrenheit  and  with  dry  summers  and  low  relative  humid- 
ity all  lean  sandy  lands  have  failed  in  maintaining  satisfactory  agri- 
culture. 

Topography  affects  agriculture ;  generally  a  five  per  cent  slope 
washes  as  soon  as  plowed ;  a  ten  per  cent  slope  gullies  and  is  ruined. 
Usually  steep  lands  become  stony  and  lean  and  millions  of  acres  of 
farm  lands  have  been  abandoned  in  Europe  because  of  topography. 

Dense  population  commonly  stimulates  the  use  of  land  for 
farming.  In  the  United  States  millions  of  acres  of  good  land  are 
not  used  or  poorly  used  for  lack  of  labor  and  demand.  But  while 
it  is  generally  true  that  dense  population  leads  to  the  use  of  lands 
for  agriculture,  this  is  no  longer  true  to  the  same  extent  that  it  was 
fifty  or  more  years  ago.  Formerly  the  majority  of  the  people  lived 
on  the  farm,  today  over  sixty  per  cent  of  the  people  of  the  United 
States  live  in  town.  The  people  do  not  flock  to  the  country,  they 
leave  the  country  and  move  to  town.  It  is  the  town  which  furnishes 
employment  and  a  safe  and  comfortable  living.  This  is  as  true  of 
Europe  as  it  is  of  the  United  States.  The  result  is  that  millions  of 
acres  of  land  even  in  the  better  populated  parts  of  the  United  States 
and  the  most  densely  populated  states  of  Europe  are  not  tilled,  and 
large  areas  have  been  abandoned  to  deteriorate  into  waste  lands. 
Dense  population  today,  means  cities,  manufacture  and  commerce, 
good  wages  and  living  in  the  city,  higher  wages  and  less  farm  labor 
for  the  farm;  and  intensive  use  of  good  farm  lands  which  justify 
labor  and  machinery ;  and  abandonment  of  poor  farm  lands.  In 
Europe  this  situation  has  shifted  the  use  of  lands  from  agriculture 
to  forestry  for  large  areas ;  it  has  led  to  regular  appropriations  by 
the  states  and  the  development  in  this  direction  is  more  rapid  today 


130 


FOREST  VALUATION 


than  ever  before.    Lands  worth  up  to  fifty  dollars  an  acre  are  today 
being  converted  from  field  into  forest  in  southern  Germany. 

England  has  had  a  special  commission  to  work  on  this  problem. 
In  its  report  this  body  cites  the  case  of  a  tract  of  land  of  twelve 
thousand  acres,  bought  at  ten  dollars  an  acre,  which  for  years  had 
brought  only  about  thirty  cents  per  acre  rental,  and  it  recommends 
extensive  purchase  of  lands  and  reforestation  in  densely  populated 
England. 

d.  The  countries  of  the  Old  World  are  interesting  in  this 
connection:  of  Scandinavia  less  than  8%  is  tilled,  about  50%  is 
waste  land;  Spain  and  Italy  are  about  33%  tilled  and  more  than 
25%  is  g°at  and  sheep  range  which  will  be  regarded  waste  land  as 
soon  as  industrial  conditions  are  such  as  to  give  the  people  a  50  cent 
per  day  wage. 

Russia  in  Europe  is  claimed  to  be  about  26%  tilled  and  37% 
forest,  leaving  37%  as  waste  land,  with  an  uncertain  portion  of 
range  lands. 

Turkey  in  Asia  tills  about  3%  of  its  580  million  acres,  the  rest 
being  mostly  waste  land  with  various  combinations  of  rock  waste, 
desert  and  range  lands. 

India,  China  and  Japan,  with  about  half  the  human  race  as 
population,  till  probably  less  than  20%  of  their  land. 

Use  of  land  in  highly  developed  states : 


Cities 

Highways 

Meadow 

and  waste 

Fields. 

and 

Forest. 

including 

Pasture. 

some 

range. 

Germany         

48 

19 

26 

6 

France                               

55 

14 

18 

13 

30 

31 

3 

36* 

Both  in  France  and  Germany  the  tilled  land  is  not  on  the  in- 
crease. Prices  of  land  are  not  advancing  and  the  rents  or  income 
from  farms  is  not  materially  better  than  fifty  years  ago. 


*  Includes  considerable  heather  land. 


LAND  CONDITIONS 

e.     Land  conditions  in  the  United  States. 


13* 


Area 

Per 

Cent. 

Region  by  States. 

million 
acres. 

Improved 
land. 

Forest. 

Rest   is 

Atlantic,  Maine  to  Georgia.  .  .  . 
Gulf,  Florida  to  Louisiana  
Texas 

225 
126 
167 

35%. 
18 

12 

45% 
65 

25 

cut  over  land 
cut  over  land 
prairie 

Lake  States,  including  Ohio, 
Indiana   and   Illinois  

207 

51 

31 

cut  over  land 

East  Central,  West  Virginia  to 
Arkansas     

146 

41 

40 

cut  over  land 

West  Central,  Oklahoma  to 
Dakota       

250 

40 

4 

prairie 

Rocky  Mountain 

C4Q 

I    C 

20 

prairie    desert 

Pacific,   California  to 
Washington          

20^ 

Q 

4O 

brush  and 
waste 
prairie,    desert, 
brush  and 

waste 

Total  United   States  

IpOO 

25 

26 

Apparently  over  900  million  acres  are  neither  forest  nor  field, 
largely  too  dry  and  therefore  prairie  or  desert.  About  300  million 
acres  are  wild  woods  on  absolute  forest  soils,  the  lands  being  un- 
suited  to  farming  by  reason  of  climate,  cold  mountain  country,  to- 
pography, all  large  mountain  ranges,  and  to  a  lesser  extent,  poor 
soil,  South  and  Lake  states  and  the  East. 

What  these  conditions  may  be  even  in  an  old  settled  state  is  well 
seen  from  the  following  figures  for  Michigan : 

State.  S.  Half.          N.  Half. 

Total  area  million  acres 36.8  17  19.8 

Per  cent  improved .35%  64%  6% 

f.     Agricultural  use. 

Generally  the  agricultural  possibilities  of  any  district  finally  de- 
cide its  use.  Any  good  tract  of  agricultural  land  as  large  as  an  ordi- 
nary county  will  become  farm  settlement  in  our  country.  This  fact, 
based  on  large  experience  has  helped  to  fix  in  the  minds  of  most 


132  FORKST  VALUATION 

people,  and  especially  the  so-called  representative  men  who  are  in 
duty  bound  to  "boost"  and  to  "believe  in  the  country,"  the  assump- 
tion that  all  lands  are  agricultural  lands.  That  this  is  practically 
true  of  Iowa  and  Illinois  no  one  doubts,  but  that  it  is  true  of  very 
few  other  states  every  one  who  cares  to  can  see  for  himself. 

Formerly  the  policy  of  the  states  was  to  get  people  and  settle 
the  country.  Usually  this  policy  was  forcefully  emphasized  by  the 
land  boomer  and  other  people  who  had,  or  believed  they  had  a  mon- 
etary interest  in  rapidly  populating  the  state.  Of  late  the  author- 
ities agree  that  the  state  wants : 

1.  Not  merely  many  people  biit  rather  good  and  prosperous 
people. 

2.  To  the  state,  any  kind  of  "pauper''  industry  or  industry  in 
which  the  people  can  not  make  fair  wages  and  a  fair  living  is  an 
injury.    Of  these  pauper  industries  the  farming  of  non-agricultural 
lands  is  one  of  the  worst. 

3.  The  state  needs  manufacture  as  well  as  farming,  and  that 
even  the  best  farming  districts  may  lose  in  population  and  business 
because  of  the  one-industry  condition.    Consider  Missouri  and  Iowa, 
and  some  of  the  best  farm  counties  of  several  of  our  states. 

4.  The  state  wants  to  have  its  people  supplied  with  raw  ma- 
terial and  manufactured  goods  by  the  state  itself  and  so  be  as  inde- 
pendent of  import  as  possible.     This  applies  as  much  to  timber  as 
to  grain. 

5.  Every  acre  of  land  should  raise  the  best  possible  crop  and 
make  the  largest  return  in  permanent  use. 

6.  Labor   conditions    should    be    carefully   balanced,    so    that 
labor  is  steadily  employed  and  all  work  is  well  done.     The  great 
wheat  districts,  though  excellent  farm  country,  waste  grain  for  lack 
of  help  in  the  harvest  season,  and  fail  to  give  employment  all  the 
rest  of  the  year. 

7.  Regulation   of   stream   flow,   protection    from  erosion   and 
winds  and  the  beauty  of  the  landscape  are  important  and  in  many 
cases  decide  the  choice  between  field  and  forest. 

In  our  country  public  policy  regarding  the  proper  use  of  land 
is  largely  controlled  by  the  views  and  wishes  of  the  farmer  and  it 
is  interesting  to  see  how  he  is  affected  by  the  choice. 

i.  The  farmer  wants  not  merely  good  crops  but  good  prices. 
A  good  home  market  is  the  only  means  of  liberating  the  farmer 


FARMER'S  VIEWPOINT  133 

from  the  speculator  and  the  manipulator  of  the  world  markets.  Two 
good  sawmills  where  twenty  per  cent  of  the  land  is  tilled  in  a  county 
of  the  Great  Lakes  district,  are  worth  more  to  these  farmers  of  the 
county  than  a  condition  of  sixty  per  cent  of  the  land  cleared,  com- 
petition trebled  and  the  local  market  spoiled  for  lack  of  manufac- 
tures. This  competition  is  especially  painful  in  one-crop  districts, 
potato,  fruit,  etc.,  and  it  is  doubly  bad  where  the  average  farmer  is 
poor  and  compelled  to  sell  for  what  he  can  get. 

2.  The  farmer  needs  labor,  cheap  and  convenient,  usually  for 
short  periods.    Without  other  business  a  district  can  not  keep  itself 
supplied. 

3.  The  farmer  needs  railways.    The  farm  furnishes  about  two 
hundred  and  fifty  pounds  of  freight  per  acre  and  year,  the  forest 
about  one  thousand  and  the  manufacturer  exceeds  them  both. 

4.  The   farmer  wants  good   roads  and  schools  and  yet  low 
taxes.    The  state  taxes,  and  these  in  the  long  run  determine  school 
and  road,  are  not  paid  by  the  farmer.     In  the  United  States  the 
farmer  owns  less  than  one-third  of  the  property,  is  assessed  at  about 
sixty  per  cent  of  its  value  and  usually  pays  about  sixty  or  seventy- 
five  per  cent  of  the  average  tax  rate  for  the  state,  so  he  contributes 
less  than  twenty  per  cent  to  the  state  tax  burden. 

It  is  evident  that  to  the  farmer  there  is  very  little  inducement  to 
urge  agricultural  use  of  lands  wherever  this  brings  competition  and 
reduces  manufacture  and  local  market.  In  the  past  this  phase  of 
the  question  was  clouded  because,  most  farmers  were  as  much  spec- 
ulators as  they  were  farmers ;  they  wanted  to  feel  that  their  farm 
was  increasing  in  value  and  that  they  would  make  money  by  selling 
out  if  they  chose  to  do  so.  The  utter  fallacy  of  this  reasoning  to  the 
real  farmer  is  apparent ;  all  he  gained  by  the  boost  was  a  larger  tax 
assessent,  for  his  crop,  and  his  income  was  not  increased  by  it.  A 
few  boost  sales  in  a  county  frequently  upset  farm  assessment  though 
they  did  not  add  a  cent  to  the  income  of  ninety-nine  per  cent  of  the 
farmers. 

g.  The  income  from  the  land  has  always  been  regarded  as  an 
important  criterion  of  its  use.  A  century  ago  before  railway  and 
modern  manufacture,  wood  was  cheap,  over  large  areas  it  had  no 
value  at  all,  while  food  was  a  necessity  and  measured  by  a  day's 
wage  was  high  in  price  everywhere.  Accordingly,  the  incomes  from 
forests  were  very  small  and  even  foresters  like  Hundeshagen  and 
Cotta  felt  that  only  the  state  could  afford  forestry  on  anything  like 


134  FOREST  VALUATION 

fair  land.  Today  these  conditions  have  changed,  and  agriculture  is 
called  on  to  explain  its  smaller  net  income  from  better  lands.  In 
this  discussion  it  is  well  to  keep  in  mind  the  following : 

1.  Timber  is  a  necessity  to  modern  civilization.     All  substi- 
tutes have  not  been  able  to  reduce  the  per  capita  consumption  and 
in  Europe  any  state  with   fair  industrial  development  becomes,  a 
timber  importer  as  soon  as  its  forest  area  drops  below  thirty  per  cent. 

2.  The  forest  crop  is  safe  and  certain  wherever  forest  is  native 
and  even  on  prairies  the  forest  once  established  modifies  its  own 
local  climate.    On  all  lean  and  difficult,  stony,  rough,  etc.,  lands  the 
forest  is  far  more  certain  than  any  field  crop.     The   forest  crop 
takes  care  of  the  land,  the  field  crop  drains  it. 

3.  The  forest  crop  is  durable,  unlike  potatoes,  fruit,  etc.     A 
few  years  seasoning  increases  the  value  of  timber. 

4.  Prices  of  forest  products  have  gone  up  steadily  for  a  cen- 
tury and  have  more  than  doubled  in  half  a  century ;  prices  of  field 
crops  in  Europe  and  the  United  States  have  not  changed  materially 
for  the  last  half  century.     See  Endres,  Forst  Politlk,  p.   119,  etc. 
Rye,  the  great  bread  stuff,  was  cheaper  in  Prussia  in  1893-1903  than 
it  was  in  1860-1890.    For  the  United  States,  see  United  States  Dept. 
Agri.  Farmer's  bulletin,  645,  1914,  p.  23,  the  value  per  acre  of  the 
ten  most  important  farm  crops  was  $15.74  in   1871,  then  declined 
rapidly  and  did  not  regain  this  value  until  1908. 

5.  Forest  statistics  of  necessity  are  averages  since  it  requires 
many  seasons  to  grow  a  crop  of  timber.     To  be  comparable  at  all 
the  figures  for  farm  income  therefore  must  be  ,taken  as  averages. 
This  is  commonly  overlooked  and  accidental  maximum  figures  are 
constantly   quoted   and   repeated.      "Great   money   in   clover-seed," 
"$400  per  acre  in  cherries,"  etc.,  are  repeated  in  journals  and  by 
booster  orators  until  the  average  person  is  completely  misled.     It 
is  one  of  the  most  useful  works  of  the  United  States  Department  of 
Agriculture  and  the  Experiment  Stations  to  gather  truthful  statis- 
tics of  the  farm.     So  long  as  the  booster  succeeds  in  making  the 
people  believe  that  there  is  big  money  in  sand  farms,  so  long  the 
public  is  reluctant  to  pay  even  a  decent  cost  price  for  farm  products. 

6.  Forest  statistics  as  used  here  describe  large  averages  of 
incomes  not  from  the  good  lands  but  from  inferior,  largely  non-agri- 
cultural lands.     It  is  doubtful  if  more  than  thirty  per  cent  of  all 
German  forest  lands  could  be  farmed  continuously  and  successfully. 
If  all  lands  of  Germany  were  arranged  in  five  classes  of  equal  area, 


INCOME  FROM   FARMLANDS  135 

the  forest  lands  would  take  practically  all  of  number  five  and  about 
half  of  number  four  with  very  little  of  class  I-III.  For  this  reason 
it  is  quite  safe  to  say  that  for  the  same  use,  the  lands  now  in  fields, 
etc.,  should  by  virtue  of  their  fertility  produce  a  much  larger  return 
than  the  forest  lands.  This  as  will  be  seen,  they  do  only  for  the 
gross  income  in  which  a  large  per  cent  is  labor,  but  they  fail  to  do 
this  for  net  income,  clearly  proving  the  superiority,  at  present  prices, 
of  the  forest  uses  when  judged  by  net  income. 

i.     Income  from  field  and  farm  land  in  the  United  States. 

For  over  thirty  years  the  United  States  Census  authorities  have 
gathered  farm  statistics.  Of  late  the  United  States  Department  of 
Agriculture  and  also  some  of  our  Agricultural  Experiment  Stations 
have  checked,  verified  and  amplified  this  work  and  have  generally 
proven  the  accuracy  of  the  work  of  the  Census.* 

In  discussing  the  income  from  land  used  in  farming  it  is  neces- 
sary to  keep  separate  the  income  from  the  crop  and  that  from  the 
animals,  etc.,  which  represent  a  separate  investment. 

The  total  value  of  the  farm  crops  in  the  United  States,  includ- 
ing the  value  of  the  material  fed  to  live  stock,  was  reported  in  cir- 
cular 132,  as  taken  from  the  Census  of  1910,  at  5,487  million  dollars, 
or  $860  per  farm.  The  average  farm  has  138  acres,  of  which  75 
acres  are  improved  land.  Allowing  only  50%  for  cost  of  produc- 
tion, exclusive  of  rent  of  land,  the  138  acres  of  farm  land  produce 
a  gross  crop  income  of  $6.24  per  acre,  or  a  net  crop  income  of  $3.12. 
Even  if  referred  to  the  75  acres  of  improved  land  only  the  gross  crop 
income  is  $11.40  and  net  $5.70  an  acre. 

United  States  Bulletin  645,  1914,  p.  23,  gives  the  "Yearly  value 
per  acre  of  ten  crops  combined."  The  crops  are  corn,  wheat,  oats, 

*  See  United  States  Crop  Reporter  for  1911  for  cost  of  producing  wheat, 
oats  and  potatoes  in  the  United  States. 

Ohio  Agricultural  Experiment  Station  bulletin  266  cost  of  producing  corn 
in  Ohio,  1913. 

United  States  Farmers'  Bulletin  641,  1914,  cost  of  producing  cotton. 

United  States  Farmers'  Bulletin  635,  what  the  farm  contributes  directly 
to  the  farmer's  living,  1914. 

United  States  Farmers'  Bulletin  645,  Agricultural  Outlook,  1914,  p.  23, 
yearly  value  per  acre  of  the  ten  most  important  crops  combined  for  1866-1914. 

Bulletin  41,  United  States  Department  of  Agriculture,  1914,  farm  manage- 
ment survey  of  three  representative  areas  in  Indiana,  Illinois  and  Iowa. 

Farmers'  Bulletin  665,  1915,  Agricultural  Outlook  for  farm  wages  in  the 
United  States;  Farmers'  Bulletin  570,  1913,  and  circular  I3^-A,  1913,  which 
discuss  the  farmers'  income,  using  Census  of  1910. 


136 


•  FOREST  VALUATION 


barley,  rye,  cotton,  potatoes,  hay,  tobacco  and  buckwheat.    The  data 
are  presented  in  the  following  diagram. 


/6 
/5 
$14 
&3 
$12 


A7 


z 


V 


L 


Fig.  2.  Chart  showing  the  value  per  acre  of  10  crops  combined  (corn, 
wheat,  oats,  barley,  rye,  buckwheat,  potatoes,  hay,  tobacco,  and  cotton),  rep- 
resenting about  90%  of  the  total  cultivated  area  of  the  United  States. 

These  figures  present  the  gross  income  per  acre  of  fields  and 
meadows,  actually  tilled  that  year,  and  show  that  even  at  present 
prices  this  gross  income  is  only  about  $16  an  acre  and  that  for  more 
than  25  years  prior  to  1904  it  was  usually  below  $12  an  acre  of  fields 
and  meadows.  These  fields  contained  47  acres  per  farm,  or  made 
only  34%  of  the  farm  itself.  The  following  table  indicates  the  rel- 
ative importance  of  the  principal  crops,  and  presents  some  figures 
on  the  cost  of  production  of  farm  crops  in  the  United  States,  1909. 


Cost  of 

Total 
area 
million 

Total 
Value 
million 

Yield 
per 

Value 
per 
acre. 

production 
per  acre 
exclusive 

acres. 

dollars. 

acre. 

$ 

of  rent. 

$ 

Corn    

10^ 

i=;2O 

32  bu. 

10 

8.52 

Wheat  

4Q 

ccc 

17  bu. 

17 

7.85 

Oats    

-ty 

4.C2 

W  bu. 

14 

7.13 

Cotton    

T.J 

825 

240  Ibs. 

3,0 

16.70 

Potatoes     

3.6 

212 

iiSbu. 

35 

25 

Hay 

AT. 

856 

1.2  tons 

14 

Barley  and  rye  

9-7 

135 

22  bu. 

ii 

about  like 

oats. 

CROP  AND  EXPANSES  ON  FARM  137 

Bulletin  645,  1914,  states  that  the  thirteen  principal  crops  occupied 
three  hundred  million  acres,  and  had  a  value  at  the  farm  of  4,919 
million  dollars,  or  about  $16.38  an  acre. 

Another  reliable  measure  of  farm-crop  income  is  the  rent  act- 
ually paid  to  owners  of  farms.  While  in  a  few  localities  the  rent 
has  been  boosted  up  to  as  high  as  $8,  the  general  average  of  cash 
rent  seems  to  be  close  to  $3,  closely  agreeing  with  the  average  net 
crop  income.  Even  this  $3  rent  per  acre  and  year  is  not  a  net  in- 
come to  the  owner  since  taxes  and  repair  of  buildings,  etc.,  must 
still  be  deducted.  It  is  also  quite  generally  conceded  that  the  farm 
is  rarely  well  kept  up  in  the  cash  rent  system. 

The  following  figures  describe  the  crop  income  conditions  in 
Germany.  They  are  taken  from  Helferich  "Deuts  Maud's  Wohl- 
stand','  and  represent  average  yields  for  1909-1913,  valued  at  cur- 
rent prices. 

Rye    $14-56  per  acre 

Wheat    21.50 

Barley    13 

Potatoes    19-20 

Oats 11.80 

Hay    12 

Which  would  indicate  a  general  average  close  to  $16  or  the  same  as 
the  present  average  for  the  United  States. 

Since  less  machinery  is  used  in  Germany  and  the  fields  are  gen- 
erally too  small  for  economical  farming,  the  cost  of  production  is 
higher  in  spite  of  cheaper  labor.  The  "Schlesische  Landschaft,"  see 
Martin,  Statik,  p.  259,  estimates  the  cost  of  producing  the  crop  as 
follows :  on  lands  of 

Class  i  cost  is  55-65%  of  value  of  crop 

2  57-6; 

3  60-70 

4  65-75 

5  72-82 

Taking  land  of  class  3  as  average  and  using  the  above  $16  aver- 
age for  crop,  the  net  income  even  from  these  fields  and  meadows  in 
Germany  is  only  $5.60  or  about  the  same  as  from  the  improved  land 
in  the  United  States. 

As  regards  the  regularity  of  income  the  figures  of  the  United 
States  Department  of  Agriculture,  see  Farmer's  bulletins  629,  641, 
645,  indicate  that  in  hay  even,  the  average  is  below  seventy  per  cent 
of  a  fair  stand.  As  stated  in  part  one,  the  state  forests  of  Wurttem- 
berg  today  cut  about  seventy-three  per  cent  of  normal,  are  still  im- 


138 


FOREST  VALUATION 


proving  and  may  be  expected  to  be  eighty  per  cent  normal  in  their 
yield  before  another  twenty  years. 

2.     Income  from  the  forest. 

Since  there  are  no  forests  in  the.  United  States  in  a  regulated 
business  condition,  it  is  necessary  to  consider  European  results. 
Even  in  Europe  it  is  only  the  state  forests  and  the  holdings  of  other 
large  owners,  cities,  etc.,  which  can  be  considered  as  properly  taken 
care  of  in  a  way  at  all  comparable  to  the  farmer's  fields. 

The  following  table  represents  large  averages  and  the  figures 
are  reliable.  The  great  difference  between  Prussia  on  one  hand  and 
Wurttemberg  and  Saxony  on  the  other  is  due  to  soil,  sand,  and 
climate,  and  in  part,  market ;  the  smaller  income  in  Bavaria  is  large- 
ly due  to  topography,  mountain  woods,  and  to  a  lack  of  develop- 
ment. In  Bavaria  and  Prussia  a  further  development,  road  build- 
ing, etc.,  will  continue  to  absorb  much  of  the  yield.  Later  on,  in 
twenty-five  or  fifty  years,  this  will  cease  and  then  the  net  income 
will  be  a  much  larger  part  of  the  total  income. 

Incomes  from  state  forests  in  Germanv:* 


Area. 

Wurttemberg  1908. 

Saxony  1911. 

Bavaria  1912. 

Prussia  1912. 

Acres. 

490,000 

431,000 

2,330,000 

6,796,000 

Total 

yearly 

$4,906,000 

$4,015,000 

$16,156,000 

$38,490,000 

income. 

Years. 

Income  per  acre. 

Income   per   acre. 

Income  per   acre. 

Income   per   acre. 

Gross. 

Net. 

Gross. 

Net. 

Gross. 

Net 

Gross. 

Net. 

1850-59 

$  3-6o 

$    2.1  1 

$  3-03 

$  1-94 

• 

$    -97 

$    -54 

1860-69 

4-73- 

2.89 

4.46 

3.21 

$  2.32 

$  1.35 

1-43 

.83 

1870-79 

5-77 

3-45 

5.76 

3-92 

2.95 

1.66 

1.98 

.97 

1880-89 

4-99 

2.70 

6.47 

4-33 

2.64 

1.30 

2.2O 

I.OI 

1890-99 

6.35 

3-87 

7-13 

4-50 

3-73 

1.81 

2.68 

1.29 

1905 

9.20 

6.10 

8-44 

5-39 

4-5-5 

2.  2O 

4.26 

2.42 

1906 

10.05 

6.78 

8.28 

5-o8 

4-95 

2.55 

4.27 

2.27 

1907 

10.90 

7-47 

9.60 

6.17 

4.90 

2.55 

4-54 

2.51 

1908 

10.00 

6.50 

9.22 

5.58 

5-50 

2.95 

445 

2.21 

1909 

9.90 

6.35 

8.96 

5-24 

6.30 

3-30 

4-53 

2.O2 

1910 

. 

9-15 

5.36 

4.22 

1-93 

1911 

• 

9.20 

6.03 

5-19 

2.98 

*  See    Endres,    Forst    Politik ;    Verhaltnisse    Wiirttembergs ;    Tharander 
Forstliches  Jahrbuch  und  Zeitschrift  fur  Forst  und  Jagdwesen.  Figures  round. 


FARM   OR  FOREST  139 

From  the  preceding  it  appears : 

1.  The  gross  income  per  acre  in  the  well  kept  forests  of  Wurt- 
temberg and  Saxony  with  present  prices  of  timber  is  larger  than 
the  gross  income  from  the  field  and  meadow  when  the  quality  of 
soil  is  considered ;  and  that  it  is  about  sixty  per  cent  of  crop  income 
even  if  no  allowance  is  made  for  the  difference  of  soil. 

In  Prussia  the  gross  income  from  forest  is  about  thirty  per  cent 
of  the  gross  income  from  the  fields,  a  difference  fully  accounted  for 
by  the  poor  quality  of  the  pinery  sands  devoted  to  forestry. 

2.  The  net  income  from  forests  in  Wiirttemberg,  Baden,  Sax- 
ony, etc.,  state  forests,  is  as  large  and  often  larger  than  the  net 
income  from  farm  lands  in  the  same  districts.     This,  of  course,  is 
chiefly  due  to  the  smaller  cost  of  production  since  this  cost  is  nor- 
mally below7  fifty  per  cent  of  the  value  of  the  crop  in  forestry  and 
above  sixty-five  per  cent  in  farming. 

3.  The  gross  crop  income  and  net  crop  income  from  farmland 
in  the  United  States  is  smaller  than  that  obtained  from  the  state 
forests  of  Wiirttemberg,  Baden,  Saxony,  etc.,  and  is  but.  little  higher 
than  that  from  the  poor  pinery  forests  of  Prussia. 

Even  if  only  the  improved  lands  of  our  farms  are  considered, 
the  gross  income  is  little  higher  than  that  of  the  state  forests  of 
Wurttemberg  and  Saxony  and  the  net  income  is  even  lower. 

To  some  extent  this  condition  is  due,  no  doubt,  to  the  fact  that 
farm  products  in  the  United  States  and  abroad  are  not  paid  for  at 
a  proper  price  in  keeping  with  the  value  of  soil  and  the  cost  of  pro- 
duction. If  correctly  adjusted  the  field  with  its  better  soil  and  large 
amount  of  labor  should  produce  at  least  twice  the  gross  income  ob- 
tained from  the  forest.  But  the  fact  remains  that  the  growth  pro- 
duced in  the  forest  is  very  large  and  also  that  the  forest,  owing  to 
the  large  crop-capital  in  the  form  of  growing  stock  is  entitled  to  a 
correspondingly  large  net  income. 
Summing  up: 

1.  The  forest  can  utilize  colder,  frostier  sites. 

2.  It  can  use  rough,  steep,  stony  and  poorly  drained  land. 

3.  It  can  use  poor  soils,  especially  sands. 

4.  It  maintains  the  fertility  of  the  soil  and  therefore  is  a  much 
surer  crop  than  any  farm  crop. 

5.-  Bad  seasons  are  averaged  up  in  forestry,  an  excellent  stand 
harvested  in  1914  may  have  been  through  many  poor  seasons  but 
their  effect  is  no  longer  seen. 

6.  Its  products  are  enduring  and  generally  gain  in  value  by 
storage. 


140  FOREST  VALUATION 

7.  The  crop  is  not  ripened  in  a  few  days  or  even  months,  but 
can  be  cut  at  any  time  from  the  age  of  fifty  to  one  hundred  and 
fifty  years. 

8.  It  requires  less  labor  than  the  farm  crop. 

Agricultural  use  on  the  other  hand : 

1.  Is  possible  or  practicable  on  probably  less  than  fifty  per 
cent  of  the  land  area  of  the  United  States. 

2.  It  is  the  most  important  use  of  land. 

3.  It  uses  more  unskilled  labor  than  forestry. 

4.  It  furnishes  greater  values  only  from  better  lands. 

5.  It  furnishes  less  material  per  acre  for  transportation  and 
further  manufacture. 

6.  It  encourages  erosion,  rapid  run  off  of  water  and  so  injures 
land  and  disturbs  water  distribution. 

3.     Use  of  land  for  range. 

Real  range  lands  occur  chiefly  in  dry  districts,  prairie  and  des- 
ert, and  mountain  countries  where  the  forest  can  not  hold  its  own 
on  account  of  conditions  of  temperature,  or  moisture,  or  both.  On 
better  prairies  of  the  West  the  range  has  given  way  to  the  farm.  On 
poor  soils  in  forest  districts  like  the  southern  pinery  and  the  sands 
of  the  Great  Lake  region  the  forage  plants  are  readily  crowded  out 
by  more  frugal  but  useless  plants,  so  that  grazing  on  these  lands  is 
of  very  little  value,  and  can  not  be  compared  with  the  use  of  these 
same  lands  for  forest.  The  poor  jack  pine  lands  will  grow  fifty 
cents  worth  of  jack  pine  and  scrub  oak  per  acre  and  year,  but  they 
will  never  be  worth  ten  cents  per  acre  and  year  continuously  as 
range. 

The  following  general  averages  describe  the  range  conditions 
in  western  United  States : 

Number  of  head  of  range  live  stock  and  their  equivalent  in 
sheep. 

United  States.  West.  Equivalent    in    sheep 

West  of  plains.  in  the  West. 

Cattle      61  million  9       million,    or    15%  50  million 

Horses    24  million  2.5  million,   or    10%  20  million 

Sheep      52  million  28       million,    or    54%  28  million 

Assuming  that  the  feed  of  a  sheep  is  worth  sixty  cents  per  year 
and  that  the  four  million  acres  of  tilled  agricultural  land  in  the  west 
furnish  one-third  of  all  the  feed,  the  range  lands,  approximately 


RANGE:  is  WASTE:  141 

four  hundred  million  acres  furnish  about  forty  million  dollars  worth 
of  feed  or  ten  cents  per  acre  and  year. 

Where  range  lands  are  leased  as  by  the  state  of  Texas  and  oth- 
ers, or  where  stock  is  grazed  at  fixed  rate  per  head  as  by  the  United 
States  Indian  Office  and  the  United  States  Department  of  Agricul- 
ture, the  price  is  generally  below  five  cents  per  acre  and  year,  or 
season.  From  these  few  figures  it  is  clear  that  where  land  can  be 
used  for  forestry  or  for  farming  the  use  as  range  is  an  inexcusable 
waste. 


APPENDIX. 


A.     Normal  Yield  Tables. 

These  tables  will  prove  useful  in  giving  actual  reliable  data  con- 
cerning forestry  as  a  business.  They  will  be  helpful  in  preparing 
problems  for  class  use. 

American  yield  tables  are  still  deficient ;  practically  all  data 
come  from  wild  woods ;  the  growth  of  the  individual  tree  is  usually 
determined  on  dominant  trees  only,  the  yields  per  acre  on  stands  far 
beyond  a  justifiable  rotation;  the  effects  of  man's  care  in  thinning 
are  yet  to  be  learned.  None  of  these  data  are  as  yet  accepted  by  a 
representative  body  of  men. 

Under  these  conditions  it  seemed  best  to  use  the  German  tables 
as  worked  out  in  connection  with  the  forest  experiment  stations 
and  compiled  by  Professor  Doctor  Adam  Schwappach,  the  foremost 
authority  in  this  line  of  study. 

The  division  into  five  sites  was  agreed  to  by  the  Experiment 
Stations  in  1888,  and  bases  the  division  on  the  total  volume  of  the 
main  stand  and  provides  for  the  stand  one  hundred  years  old  the 
following  relations: 

Site.  Pine.  Spruce  and  fir.  Beech. 

I  100  100  100 

II  78  82  80 

III  60  66  64 

IV  43  •  50  49 

V  29  36  35 

In  Schwappach's  tables  this  relation  is  fairly  adhered  to  as  is 
apparent  from  the  following:  total  volume  of  the  pure  fully  stocked 
normal  stand  one  hundred  years  old  is : 

Site.  Pine.          Spruce.  Oak.  Beech. 

I 
I 

II 
III 
IV 
V 


6600  c.  ft. 

11600 

6200 

IOIOO 

100 

100 

IOO 

ICO 

85 

83 

79 

80 

69 

66 

58 

64 

55 

5i 

— 

49 

43 

36 

— 

35 

144 


FOREST  VALUATION 


Since  these  German  tables  can  not  be  used  in  the  United  States 
without  modification,  it  seemed  unnecessary  to  tabulate  for  all  rive 
sites,  and  only  the  figures  for  site  II  as  nearly  a  good  average,  are 
here  reproduced.  Most  of  the  figures  are  rounded  off.  The  graphs, 
figures  3-8,  follow  Schwappach's  as  given  in  his  admirable  "Fvrtrag- 
stafeln  d.  wichtigeren  Holzarten,"  1912. 

How  far  these  tables  may  serve  to  guide  and  check  in  our  work 
in  the  United  States  is  yet  to  be  learned.  It  seems  reasonable,  how- 
ever, that  for  trees  of  similar  habits,  tolerance  and  soil  requirements, 
etc.,  the  yield  per  acre  is  well  indicated  by  height  growth,  and  that 
as  a  provisional  check  we  may  assume  that  if  spruce  in  a  certain 
district  in  the  United  States  has  #  height  growth  equal  to  that  of 
spruce  site  III  in  Germany,  the  yield  per  acre  will  also  approximate 
that  of  site  III,  etc. 


MONEY  YIELD  TABI&  FOR  SPRUCE,  SITE  II. 

Middle  and  N.  Germany :   Sdhwappach ;   1902. 

Only  wood  3"  and  over  (Derbholz)   considered. 


Age. 

Main  Stand. 
Price      Value 

Thin- 
nings 
added. 

Total 
value. 
Main 
stand 
and 

Average  Tree 
Main  Stand. 

of 

TreVs 

per 

total 

Value 

thin- 

Diam 

per 

100 

per 

per 

nings 

Height 

b.h. 

Vol- 

Value 

acre. 

c.  ft. 

acre. 

acre. 

per 

o.b. 

ume 

acre. 

$ 

$ 

.  '$ 

$ 

ft. 

inch. 

c.  ft. 

$ 

30 

1800 

4.80 

56 



56 

27 

3-2 

0.5 

0.03 

40 

1  020 

6.70 

172 

10 

182 

4i 

4-8 

2-5 

0.17 

50 

680 

8.60 

366 

4i 

407 

56 

6.4 

6. 

0-54 

60 

485 

9-30 

54i 

104 

645 

67 

8. 

12.8 

i.  n 

70 

372 

1  1.  60 

803 

207 

IOIO 

76 

9-5 

>i8.8 

2.15 

80 

295 

12.60 

9/2 

336 

1308 

83 

10.8 

26.5 

3-28 

90 

239 

13-25 

1092 

483 

1575 

90 

12.  1 

34-5 

4-50 

100 

198 

13-80 

1183 

648 

1831 

96 

13-3 

44- 

5-9^ 

no 

167 

14.40 

1260 

814 

2074 

101 

14-3 

53- 

7-50 

120 

140 

14.80 

T305 

969 

2274 

105 

15-6 

64- 

9-25 

APPENDIX  145 


MONEY  YIELD  TABLE  FOR  PINE,  SITE  II. 

In  N.  Germany,  Schwappach,  Kiefer,  1908. 

Only  for  wood  3"  and  over  (Derbholz). 


Main  Stand. 

Thin- 
nings 

Total 
value. 
Main 
stand 

Average  Tree  of 
Main  Stand. 

Age. 

Price 

Value 

added. 

and 

Trees 

per 

total 

Value 

thin- 

Height 

Diam. 

Vol- 

Value 

per 

IOO 

per 

per 

nings 

ulme 

acre. 

c.  ft. 

acre. 

acre. 

per 

acre. 

$ 

$ 

$ 

$ 

ft. 

inch. 

c.  ft. 

$ 

30 

1560 

5.8o 

133 

17 

150 

33 

3-7 

.0.9 

0.08 

40 

840 

6.10 

201 

55 

,256 

43 

5-3 

3- 

0.24 

50 

550 

6.40 

267 

98 

365 

52 

6-7 

6. 

0.48 

60 

400 

6.70 

333 

143 

476 

59 

8.0 

9-5 

0.83 

70 

290 

7.10 

423 

190 

613 

65 

9-2 

14. 

1-45 

80 

240 

7.70 

499 

242 

74i 

7i 

10.5 

19. 

2.05 

90 

200 

8.40 

567 

299 

866 

75 

n-5 

24-5 

2.83 

IOO 

160 

9.20 

623 

36o 

983 

79 

12.5 

32. 

3-90 

no 

140 

IO.20 

700 

428 

1128 

83 

13-5 

37- 

5-00 

120 

120 

II.  2O 

770 

501 

1271 

85 

145 

44- 

6.40 

130 

105 

I2.OO 

838 

574 

1412 

87 

15-2 

50. 

8.00 

140 

96 

12.80 

859 

639 

1498 

89 

15-6 

54- 

8.90 

146 


VALUATION 


MONEY  YIELD  TABLE  FOR  OAK,  SITE  II. 

In  N.  Germany,  Schwappach,  1905. 
Only  the  Yield  of  Stuff  3"  and  over  (Derbholz). 


Main  Stand. 
Price      Value 

Thin- 
nings 
added. 

Total 
value. 
Main 
stand 
and 

Average  Tree  of 
Main  Stand. 

Age. 

Trees 

per 

total 

Value 

thin- 

per 

100 

per 

per 

nings 

Height 

Diam. 

Vol- 

Value 

acre. 

c.  ft. 

acre. 

acre. 

per 

ume 

acre. 

$* 

$ 

$ 

$ 

ft. 

inch. 

c.  ft. 

$ 

30 

2650 

7.85 

39 



39 

26 

2. 



O.OI 

40 

1240 

7.85 

82 

27 

109 

35 

3- 

— 

0.06 

50 

610 

7.85 

no 

86 

196 

43 

4-9 

2.5 

0.18 

60 

370 

7.85 

150 

155 

305 

51 

7- 

6. 

0.40 

70 

260 

7-85 

202 

222 

424 

59 

8.5 

10.5 

0.77 

80 

195 

7.85 

244 

28l 

525 

64 

10. 

17-5 

1.25 

90 

145 

7-85 

295 

332 

627 

69 

11.5 

27. 

2.06 

100 

125 

8.60 

373 

374 

747 

73 

13- 

36. 

3.00 

no 

no 

IO.OO 

476 

410 

886 

76 

15- 

44- 

4-34 

120 

96 

11.50 

584 

442 

1026 

79 

16. 

54- 

6.05 

130 

86 

13.60 

735 

472 

1207 

82 

17. 

64- 

8.50 

140 

78 

15.80 

895 

503 

1398 

85 

18. 

74- 

11.40 

150 

7i 

17.20 

I02O 

535 

1555 

.    88 

19. 

86. 

14.30 

160 

65 

18.00 

IIOO 

564 

1664 

00 

19.7 

97- 

16.90 

I/O 

60 

18.60 

1177 

645 

1822 

92 

20.5 

108. 

19.60 

180 

55 

19.40 

1242 

690 

1932 

94 

21.2 

120. 

22.50 

190 

5i 

19.40 

1277 

736 

2013 

96 

22, 

130. 

25.00 

200 

48 

19.40 

I206 

786 

2082 

97 

22.6 

I4O. 

27.00 

*For  the  Stand  below  looy  the  value  of  n  Mark  pro.  F.  m.  was  used  as 
the  nearest  average. 


APPENDIX 


MONEY  YIELD  TABLE  FOR  BEECH,  SITE  II. 

N.  Germany;  Schwappach;  ion. 
Only  wood  3"  and  over  (Derbholz). 
Heavy  Thinning  (Lockerer  Schluss). 


Main  Stand. 
Price 

Value 

Thin- 
nings 
added. 

Total 
value. 
Main 
stand 
and 

Average  Tree  of 
Main  Stand. 

Age. 

Trees 

per 

total 

Value- 

thin- 

Diam 

per 

100 

per 

per 

nings 

Height 

b.h. 

Vol- 

Value 

acre. 

c.  ft. 

acre. 

acre. 

per 

o.b. 

ume 

acre. 

$ 

$ 

$ 

$ 

ft. 

inch. 

c.ft. 

$ 

30 

2900 









28 

2. 





40 

2IOO 

3-10 

4i 

i 

42 

4i 

2.8 

0.6 

O.O2 

50 

1360 

3-8o 

88 

19 

107 

52 

3-8 

i-7 

O.O6 

60 

780 

4-15 

127 

57 

184 

62 

5-i 

4.0 

0.16 

70 

430 

4-50 

166 

103 

269 

72 

6.8 

8-5 

0.38 

So 

260 

4-90 

205 

154 

359 

78 

8-5 

15-6 

0.79 

90 

187 

5-30 

248 

208 

456 

85 

10.4 

23- 

1.30 

100 

153 

5-6o 

292 

267 

559 

9i 

II.2 

3i. 

1.90 

no 

131 

5-90 

34i 

328 

669 

96 

12.2 

39- 

2.60 

120 

112 

6.30 

388 

393 

78i 

IOI 

13.2 

47- 

3-45 

130 

93 

6.60 

428 

460 

888 

105 

14-3 

59- 

4.60 

140 

76 

7.00 

458- 

529 

987 

109 

15-8 

70. 

6.00 

148 


FOREST  VALUATION 


!£*§  's       * 

U»S   ^^S5 

ON  Tf  ON  NO 
co  co  04   04 

CO  M   MOO 
04    04    04    M 

tx\O  Tf  co 

8 

dill  .si     * 

«5S     o^«|^ 

co  ol  8  ON 

^K«^ 

ssa8 

& 

^            o 

t—  t    M    HH          04    04    04    04 

*04    04    ^4    >—* 

0 

03 

0, 

a                      *rt          £ 

t—  i    co  tO^O        OO    O    *•"  '    04 

S%9^ 

ON  O  04  01 

Tf  to  to  to 

aoo? 

rd 

f  1  |  !          ^ 

O 
CO 

'I'Sh    u 

xt"  to  CO  CO         to  to  01  VO 

ON  O  ON  ON 

to  co  ON  tx 
ON  ONOOOO 

CO  Q  tx  to 
00  00  tx  tx 

03 

3_, 

|  ||^|         ^ 

r^-\O    O         COVO   ON  04 

M              1-1     M     t-i     O4 

W8RS 

VOOO    O    04 
•CO  co  ^t  r^- 

?^i 

<U 

£H  *S   £        •M 

O 

_fi 

__  o 

I'S 

§•§  g^c'S    8^ 

CO  O  00  00          0s.  O   CO  to/ 
H-I   n   Ol         CO  iO\O   tx/ 

^^^ 

Oi  co  ^-  to 

^v8  FJ.R 

fcl 

^£" 

1 

11 

3s    -*-1 

<u  <u        O  °          • 

I     M   co        toOO   04   lx 

%<%$$ 

\O   04   O"  to 

Tf  to  IOVO 

M  tx  co  ON 
tx  txOO  00 

^^ 

Go       t"1 

11 

1    |s      g     •g+j 

/  0*000      o^oo 

Qo  QO 

tooto^ 

0000 

c-e 

a    -^.S'C**!  • 

M           04    CO  CO  ^t 

IT;  i/-^  to\O 

NCVO^vS" 

vo'vO  to  to 

~o 

•J                        EH         p,° 

• 

S£ 

H  o 

•         « 

O  MH    <L> 

O   O   O        00   04   04   co 

•^f^O  ^4         O   co  M  OO 
^^4  co        04   w   M 

04    VH    04   to 
NO  to  Tj-  CO 

R^saa 

^2^2-^ 

K-s 

<y\o 

II 

O4O\<Nto        IxQtxto 
04CO-TfT3'         -^-tototo 

01  oo,  ^oo 

i^i^ 

CO  O   tx  to 
tx  IXNO  \O 

5^ 

"   «+H 

P<    0 

PL,  0 
CO  £ 

*^  £  £     gd 

^Otxto        ^^.-00 

NO^RS^ 

M    fo  to  tx 

00000060 

OO  ON  ON  O 
00000^    CN 

P4,b 

>   «^03          M    d 

26 

.  g        ^ 

tOOlvoOO        vO^J-040 

00  to  04  00 

to  M  tx  co 

VO   CO  OVO 

w 

^          -^-^  "•  ~*       e 

04  CO  co  ^f        tovd  txOO" 

00  ON  O  O 

1-1    04    04    CO 

CO  '•sf'  to  to 

rt 

|             Q-0  °     — 

< 

CO 

Q 

.s         >•§      ^ 

QtX-rJ-M           ONtOOllX 
04    04    CO  ^T         Tt-  tO\O  ^O 

01  \O   O   co 
tx  txOOOO 

00  ON  ON  O\ 

ON  I-H  co  to 

ON  O  O  O 

W 

i—  i 

K  c 

,1 

s  §1  « 

OO  ON  1-1  Ol         co  ^  tovt5 

r^-QQ     C>1    tO 

txOO  ON  ON 

00000005 

VQ  to  Tf  04 

00  00  00  00 

NORMA1 

O'M-I   S   *-"    ^ 

OQOO         olOOOto 
toOO   co  O        00  NO  to  "^" 

co  04   O  to 

Ol   tx  co  ON 
•rf-  co  CO  04 

10  ON  txoo 

VC  co  •-"  ON 

01  tx  co  O 
00  VC    to  Tf 

HH     l-i     M     M 

1 

to  O  to  O        10  O  'O  O 

04   co  co  ^f        ^f  to  toNO 

to  O  to  Q 
\O   lx  txOO 

S&S| 

to  O  «-o  p 

O   >-i   M   01 

APPENDIX 


149 


O 


bJ3J^-£ 
rt  u.   > 

gSl 


Q 

C^ 

'rt  £ 
%Z 


o  n  o 
'•8*">S  rt^ 

£     1|§ 

C          pH  ^ 
^ 

j3      S  L.'O 

>      ^  o-r: 

^  ft  ^ 


loll 
^    u  « 


u   ft  ° 

^_i  Cu 


II 


^t  ^^  ^    oq  vq  co 
to  d  tx    to  xt-  co  co     oi  01  04* 


^t-  co  04  M     q 
_;_;_;_;     w  p  o"  o 


ON  to  04  tx      co  ON  Tf  O 

OO  00  00  tx      txvovovo 


Qs 
co 


M  co  co  co 

ON  ON  ON  ON 


co  to  IOVQ     vo  vo  vO  vo     vo  vO 
rf  ON  rt-OO       01  toOO   O       Ol   rf 


o^  co"  coo? 


^-  rj-  CO  CO 


0^   CO  rj- 
to  to  to 


VO  co  O      VO  -sT-  O  to      O   T}-  O\  Tt-      O   ^00   01 
•-<   04   co      fO^toto     VOVOVOtx     OOOOOOCy. 


tOOO     M  Tf-tXON^  lOtxONI-l 

COCO^        ^t^fTtlO        tOlO  tOVO 


go     ooo^     oop 
co    vo  ix  ON  ON      O1.  ON  O 
"-"MO!        010)0101        0101CO 


tx  q  \o  N    oo  ^vq  co     rj-  q  vo  vo 
co  o  to  to     ^  co  01'  M     o  o*  oS  o\ 


0  O  O 
•§-  co  01 

01  01   01 


1111  §&^ 


qqqtx    txtxtxoi    ooTt-otx 
ON  d\  o\od    odododod     txtxtxto 


OOQO       Ototo-'t 


O  O   O 


^o  O  10 
M   (N  rq 


qtxtoco    |-4.t>coq    vqoioqto 

co  co  TJ- 10     vo'vd  txOO      00  O\  ON  O 


qtoqto     q^O"?    q^  "^^q 
i-ii-Hoioi     coco^i-^f    toiototo 


VO     M 

C^   CO 


01  toOO  M       cototxON      McorTio     vo  txOO  ON 
vovONOtx      txtxtxtx     00000000      OOOOOOOO 


CO  CO  01   Ol 


O  vo  OO  rf 
04   10  000 


coco^vf     II^'S      S^^^      § 


100100      tooiop      'oOtoO      toQtoO      toptoo 
01  co  co  Tf      Tf  to  tovo     vo  tx  txOO     OOOvONO       O^^oi 


150 


FOREST  VALUATION 


,00       vq  04        w   co 

ONVO       CO04        OON      0000 

txvo 

J-.           o 

VOO4        Olx       vo^       CO04 

^^     _;_;     MO     do 

d  d 

"r*  r^i*^  ^     I~H         ^^ 

l-l     M            HH 

^>  *^  j>  Q 

tl  rt  o  rt 

5£o  §.  ^    ti 

aa  ^  3a  s& 

tx  ^"       O^vO        Q   ^       04   ON 
OO  tx     vo  vo      vO  vO      vo  ^* 

5* 

1 

a>>J5ti    1      * 

ONVO      O4VO       txT}-oOQ 
M   Co      vovo        t^OO      00   O\ 

as8  &s  as  ^ 

^ 

rt  *"£^    £>   o        ^ 

,13 

<U    ^    6    ^ 

I 

<£o£    'I'S    ^ 

l^vo       04tx        04CO       -r1"r:t' 
M04        COCO        ^T  ^"       ^T^T 

•^J-  co       co  04        O   O        O\OQ 

CO  CO 

P* 

^^     u 

.13 

^  c  g'o  o         ^ 

M04         CO^        rj-Tj-.vovo 

OO        HH   M        HH(N        04CO 
vovo       VOVO       vovo       vovo 

CO  Tj- 
VO  vo 

IH 

^H-^  c      -*-• 

OS 

-gij  o.2*o      S1^ 

vo  rf      vo  QN      Tf  tx     -Q  Q 

^    28   ^S,   ft^ 

vO   O 
•<*•  vo 

03    N 

^Pk*' 

6*0 

tS-e 

o           .18^' 

[    TJ-      O  tx     vp  co      O  vo 

i                      M     M            f4     CO          T(-   Tf 

O-^-O004        voc\       04vo 

Rc» 

<u 

T3                fl   *-•        C^ 

^7  ^^ 

^H  ^ 

C    en                rt 

flj 

^1  Is.  lsl« 

IO        OO        QO        OO 

OO        QQ        QO        OO 
OO       CO       OO       OO 
vo^-       ^-^-       co^f-       coco 

IPo 

L"   C                                    -^     OH   gj     .J 

i—  t 

crt  "^                            C"1          O< 

<u 

*2tH 

n° 

o 

<->                                             .              CT5 

O       O   O        O  vo      Q   O 
i-i        co  §•       M  VO       vo  04 

vo  ^-       O  00       txVO       vovo 

M     h-l           H< 

^-CO 

.,  ri 

-M 

1-1 

°1 

|| 

TJ-  O       vooO'       O   H<        HH   04 
CO^       "^•"^       vovo       vovo 

O  04        co  vo     vO  ^^       ON  04 
0404        0404        O4O4        O4CO 
vovo       vovo       vovo       vovo 

vo  tx 

cO  cO 
vo  vo 

O  ^ 

ft^-, 

ft  v, 

go 

visits 

CO 
vo  ON       vo  04        OO    ^^       O   vo 

O\  04        VOOO        >->   CO       vovo 
T^-  vo      vo  vO     vO  vO      ^O  vO 

^ 

< 

" 

S                 o        « 

04       ON           vo           vo 

VO 

vo 

T3*         c^  ^  ^         >•        »C 

04CO       ^txOOd        MCO 

vovo       1^x00        O^  O        O   I~H 

O4-   04 

s 

§    5^°'    <    ^ 

+-> 

w 

^-» 

•?  . 

1—  1 

c               •  »^ 

^"co       3£       v^vB"     v^r^ 

"RR     0000      §8  S\      ONOS 

"SNO 

^ 

i     <!   " 

§ 

g^l'l  « 

{XM        00       <££       04   tx 

?,^      ^fc      coco      coc^ 

co°, 

0 

<j        ^j   gj         ^ 

fc 

M 

CO                 . 

O  «-M      flj     g_)     J_, 

vo^      HH  t>»     VOON      ^f04 

O  ^Q      ^Q  ^0       *~*  ^-^      Q  *^ 
w  ON    oo  rx     t^*O     ^o  10 

uo^- 

^      °H      ^^ 

vrjO^      vOcO       04Hi       i-Ht-i 

bo 

^^    05     Ro     &S 

00       00       O^       ,0^ 

QN  O 

•^ 

hH     M            IH 

APPENDIX 


c  ^"5  S 

<uTJ  fe  o 


C   bfl^^   rt 

'.5.5  S  o-g 

^H    C    S  ** 


I|-SJ§ 


O 

-o  g  2 

c  .      So 

03  ™         3   03 


II* 


o^ 

^  ° 


o  a 

*o'fc-8    - 
^§.§5    d 


<•« 


OMH 

^:  O 


Tt"     00  00   04  ^O        O  *O   ^  00      VO   ^  01   O 
O\      IxvOMDio      IOTJ-TJ-CO     co  co  <o  co 


o^oo  ixvq      T}-  co  ci 
oi  oi  oi  oi      oi  oi  <M 


M  vo  O\ 

C\  ON  ON 


M   <N    C^l    O 

to  to  to  to 


^.       txO^Ol-l       Cico 

to  ^~  to  to      to  to^O  \O      ^O  ^O  ^ 


oo 


rf  to          ' 


tO   t-l\O     M 


t-n  \O        0)  CO   CO  ON 
M   i-i        0<   01   ro  co 


R   2&88>  vSRRR  RRRR   RRRR  R£&& 

OlcO"^"tO       totOlOio       tOtOtoiO       lOlOtOiototototo 


;tO010J        t-i-rfi-iVO        lOOlOli-i        M   M    M 
CO  CO  01        O<   M   M 


ON      O  O\  ONOO 


00  2-     S^ 


nit  ia§s  im 


Tf  tO  to  to       to  to  to  IO 


O\OO  tx  to      T|-  ^00   01       tx  01  tx  01       tx  CO  p  00_ 
IOVC5  txOO'       O^OO1-^        MOioico       cO^toio 


rf  co  (N   i-i 


- 


QtoO      tootoO      toOtoO      100*00 

CO  co  Tf       rf  to  to\O      \O  IX  IXOO      OO   O\  O  O 


SO      60      10      80      <JO      too 


10 


Fig.  3.  Pine;  North  Germany  Sites  I-V;  Normal  Yield  of  main  stand  in  cubic  feet 
<acre.  Also  the  points  indicating  the  age  at  whic'h  the  average  tree  attains  a  diameter 
8",  10",  12"  and  a  'height  of  30  ft.,  40  ft.,  etc.  Only  wood  3"  and  over  is  here  considered. 

152 


30 


60        70       #0       JO       /CO 


per  acre 
CjOOO  c.jJ 


H. 


H/ta 


7ooo 
6ooo 

Sooo 
i 

^000 


H50- 


s 


s 


\ 


yFig.  4.  Spruce;  Middle  and  North  Germany;  Sites  I-V;  Normal  Yield  of 
Main  Stand  in  cubic  ft  per  acre.  Also  the  points  indicating  at  what  age  the  average 
tree  attains  a  diameter  of  8",  10"  and  12",  and  a  height  of  40  ft,  50  ft,  etc.  Only 
wood  3"  and  over  is  here  considered. 

153 


SO 


13000 


60        70         SO         <?0 

AV 


/CO          //O 

/soo< 


6000 


//o 


Fig.  5.  White  fir;  South  Germany;  Sites  I-IV;  Normal  Yield  of 
Main  Stand  in  cubic  feet  per  acre.  Also  the  points  indicating  at  what  age 
the  average  tree  attains  a  diameter  of  8",  10",  etc.,  and  a  height  of  60  ft., 
70  ft,  etc.  Only  wood  3"  and  over  is  here  considered. 

154 


7O      SO      70      100      //O      /ZO    /30 


/SO    /60    /7O    /#O    /<?0 


8000  c.  J 


6000 


6 


2.000 


/ooo  c. 


70 


Vooo 


3ooo 


^000 


/ooo 


/JO 


Fig.  6.  White  Oak  ;  N.  Germany  ;  Sites  I-III  ;  Normal  Yield  of  Main  Stand  in  cubic  feet 
per  acre.  Also  points  indicating  at  what  age  the  average  tree  attains  a  diameter  of  12",  16", 
24",  and  a  height  of  60  ft.,  70  ft.,  etc.  Only  wood  3"  and  over  is  here  considered. 

155 


SO      60     70      gO      CfO     100     HO     I2O    130 

Aae 
«  H 

Tl 

froooe^h 


70  OO 


bOQO 


/3O 


Fig.  7.  Beech;  N.  Germany;  Sites  I-V;  Normal  Yield  of  Main  Stand 
in  cubic  ft.  per  acre.  Also  points  indicating  at  what  age  the  average  tree 
attains  a  diameter  of  8",  10",  etc.,  and  a  height  of  50  ft.,  60  ft.,  etc.  Only 
wood  3"  and  over  is  here  considered. 

156 


APPENDIX  157 

B.     Tables  of  prolongation  and  discount. 

The  following  tables  follow  Kraft's  in  his  "Zuwachsrechnun- 
gen."  Their  use  is  best  illustrated  by  a  few  examples: 

1.  To  find  capital,  Cn. 

A  stand  of  timber  has  now  5,500  cubic  feet  per  acre;  a  growth 
study  determines  that  it  is  growing  at  2.5%.  What  will  this  stand 
contain  in  15  years,  growth  being  assumed  to  continue  at  present 
rate? 

Under  2.5%  find  figure  1.448  opposite  15  years;  multiply  5,500 
by  1.448,  result  is  the  volume  per  acre  in  15  years.  The  figure  1.448 
is  I.O2515. 

2.  To  find  the  initial  capital  Co.     Same  stand  during  the  last 
10  years  grew  at  rate  of  3%.    What  was  the  volume  10  years  ago? 
Find  in  column  of  3%  the  figure  1.343  opposite  10  years.     Divide 
5,500  by  1.343,  result  is  the  volume  10  years  ago. 

3.  To  find  the  growth  in  per  cent.    A  stand  now  50  years  old 
can  be  sold  at  $6.10  per  100  cubic  feet.   From  a  growth  study  it  is 
evident  that  if  kept  until  70  years  old  the  stand  would  bring  $10  per 
100  cubic  feet.     What  is  the  per  cent  growth  in  quality  these  20 

Cn  10 

years?  Keeping  in  mind  that is  i.opn  we  have  i.op20  = = 

Co  6.10 

1.638  and  p  the  rate  of  growth,  2.%.    In  teresting  and  convenient  to 
use  in  this  connection  is  the  fact  that  the  capital  growing  at  com- 

72 

pound  interest  doubles,  approximately,  every  — •  years.     To  illus- 

P 

trate,  one  dollar,  or  one  cubic  foot  grows  into  two  dollars  or  two 

72 

cubic  feet  at  3%  in  —  =-.24  years. 
3 


158  FOREST  VALUATION 


Short  Table  .of 


Years 

Values  of  1.0pn,  where  p  — 

n 

2 

2,5 

3 

3,5 

4 

4,5 

5 

10 

1,21 

1,28 

1,34 

1,41 

1,48 

1,55 

1,62 

20 

1,48 

1,63 

1,80 

1,98 

2,19 

2,41 

2,65 

30 

1,81 

2,09 

2,42 

2,80 

a,24 

3,74 

4,32 

40 

2,20 

2,68 

3,26 

3,95 

4,80 

5,81 

7,04 

50 

2,69 

3,43 

4,38 

5,58 

7,10 

9,03 

11,46 

60 

3,28 

4,39 

5,89 

7,87 

10,51 

14,02 

18,67 

70 

3,99 

5,63 

7,91 

11,11 

15,57 

21,78 

30,42 

80 

4,87 

7,20 

10,64 

15,67 

23,04 

33,93 

49,56 

90 

5,94 

9,22 

14,30 

22,11 

34,11 

52,53 

80,73 

100 

7,24 

11,81 

19,21 

31,19 

50,50 

81,58 

131,5 

110 

8,83 

15,12 

25,82 

43,9? 

74,75 

126,7 

214,2 

120 

10,76 

19,35 

34,71 

62,06 

110,6 

196,7 

348,9 

130 

13.12 

24,78 

46,64 

87,54 

163,8 

305,5 

568,3 

140 

15,99 

31,72 

62,69 

123,4 

242,4 

474,5 

925,7 

150 

19,49 

40,60 

84,25 

174,2 

358,9 

736,9 

1507 

160 

23,76 

51,97 

113,2 

245,7 

531,2 

. 

170 

28,97 

66,53 

152,1 

346,6 

786,4 



180 

35,32 

85,17 

204,5 

488,9 

1164 





190 

43,05 

109,0 

274,8 

689,7 

1723 





200 

52,48 

139,5 

369,3 

972,9 

2550 





APPENDIX 


159 


Years 
n 

0,1 

0,2 

Values  of  : 
0,3         0,4 

L.0pn,  where  p 
0,5         0,6 

0,7 

0,8 

0,9 

1,0 

1 

1,001 

1,002 

1,003 

1,004 

1,005 

1,006 

1,007 

1,008 

1,009 

1,010 

2 

1,002 

1,004 

1,006 

1,008 

1,010 

1,012 

1,014 

1,016 

1,018 

1,020 

3 

1,003 

1,006 

1,009 

1,012 

1,015 

1,018 

1,021 

1,024 

1,027 

1,030 

4 

1,004 

1,008 

1,012 

1,016 

1,020 

1,024 

1,028 

1,032 

1,036 

1,041 

5 

1,005 

1,010 

1,015 

1,020 

1,025 

1,030 

1,035 

1,041 

1,046 

1,051 

6 

1,006 

1,012 

1,018 

1.024 

1,030 

1,037 

1,043 

1,049 

1,055 

1,062 

7 

1,007 

1,014 

1,021 

1,028 

1,036 

1,043 

1,050 

1,057 

1,065 

1,072 

8 

1,008 

1,016 

1,024 

1,032 

1,041 

1,049 

1,057 

1,066 

1,074 

1,083 

9 

1,009 

1,018 

1,027 

1,037 

1,046 

1,055 

1,065 

1,074 

1,084 

1,094 

10 

1,010 

1,020 

1,030 

1,041 

1,051 

1,062 

1,072 

1,083 

1,094 

1,105 

11 

1,011 

1,022 

1,033 

1,045 

1,056 

1,068 

1,080 

1,092 

1,104 

1,116 

12 

1,012 

1,024 

1,037 

1,049 

1,062 

1,074 

1,087 

1,100 

1,114 

1,127 

13 

1,013 

1,026 

1,040 

1,053 

1,067 

1,081 

1,095 

1,109 

1,124 

1,138 

14 

1,014 

1,028 

1,043 

1,057 

1,072 

1,087 

1,103 

1,118 

1,134 

1,149 

15 

1,015 

1,030 

1,046 

1,062 

1,078 

1,094 

1,110 

1,127 

1,144 

1,161 

16 

1,016 

1,032 

1,049 

1,066 

1,083 

1,100 

1,118 

1,136 

1,154 

1,173 

17 

1,017 

1,035 

1,052 

1,070 

1,088 

1,107 

1,126 

1,145 

1,165 

1,184 

18 

1,018 

1,037 

1,055 

1,075 

1,094 

1,113 

1,134 

1,154 

1,175 

1,196 

19 

1,019 

1.039 

1,059 

1,079 

1,099 

1,120 

1,142 

1,163 

1,186 

1,208 

20 

1,020 

1,041 

1,062 

1,083 

1,105 

1,127 

1,150 

1,173 

1,196 

1,220 

21 

1,021 

1,043 

1,065 

1.087 

1,110 

1,134 

1,158 

1,182 

1,207 

1,232 

22 

1,022 

1,045 

1,068 

1,092 

1,116 

1,141 

1,166 

1,192 

1,218 

1,245 

23 

1,023 

1,047 

1,071 

1,096 

1,122 

1,148 

1,174 

1,201 

1,229 

1,257 

24 

1,024 

1,049 

1,075 

1,101 

1,127 

1,154 

1,182 

1,211 

1,240 

1,270 

25 

1,025 

1,051 

1,078 

1,105 

1,133 

1,161 

1,190 

1,220 

1,251 

1,282 

26 

1,026 

1,053 

1,081 

1,109 

1,138 

1,168 

1,199 

1,230 

1,262 

1,295 

<>r- 

».  1 

1,027 

1,055 

1,084 

1,114 

1,144 

1,175 

1,207 

1,240 

1,274 

1,308 

28 

1,028 

1,058 

1,087 

1,118 

1,150 

1,182 

1,216 

1,250 

1,285 

1,321 

29 

1,029 

1,060 

X091 

1,123 

1,156 

1,189 

1,224 

1,260 

1,297 

1,334 

30 

1,030 

1,062 

1,094 

1,127 

1,161 

1,197 

1,233 

1,270 

1,308 

1,348 

35 

1,036 

1,072 

1,111 

1,150 

1,191 

1,233 

1,277 

1,322 

1,368 

1,417 

40 

1,041 

1,083 

1,127 

1,173 

1,221 

1,270 

1,322 

1,375 

1,431 

1,489 

45 

1,046 

1,094 

1,144 

1,197 

1£52 

1,309 

1,369 

1,431 

1,497 

1,565 

50 

1,051 

1,105 

1,162 

1,221 

1,283 

1,349 

1,417 

1,490 

1,565 

1,645 

55 

1,057 

1,116 

1,179 

1,246 

1,316 

1,390 

1,468 

1,550 

1,637 

1,729 

€0 

1,062 

1,1-27 

1,197 

1,271 

1,349 

1,432 

1,520 

1,613 

1,712 

1,817 

65 

1,067 

1,139 

1,215 

1,296 

1,383 

1,475 

1,574 

1,679 

1,790 

1,909 

70 

1,072 

1,150 

1,233 

1,322 

1,418 

1,520 

1,630 

1,747 

1,872 

2,007 

75 

1,078 

1,162 

1,252 

1.349 

1,454 

1,566 

1,687 

1,818 

1,958 

2,109 

80 

1,083 

1,173 

1,271 

1,376 

1,490 

1,614 

1,747 

1,892 

2,048 

2,217 

85 

1,089 

1,185 

1,290 

1,404 

1,528 

1,663 

1,809 

1,969 

2,142 

2,330 

90 

1,094 

1,197 

1,309 

1,432 

1,567 

1,713 

1,874 

2,049 

2,240 

2,449 

95 

1,100 

1,209 

1,329 

1,461 

1,606 

1,765 

1,940 

2,132 

2,342 

2,574 

100 

1,105 

1,221 

1,349 

1,491 

1,647 

1,819 

2,009 

2,219 

2,450 

2,705 

110 

1,116 

1,246 

1,390 

1,551 

1,731 

1,931 

2,154 

2,402 

2,680 

2,988 

120 

1,127 

1,271 

1,433 

1,615 

1,819 

2,050 

2,310 

2,602 

2,931 

3,300 

i6o 


FOREST  VALUATION 


Years 
n           1,1 

1,2 

Values  of  1.0pn,  where  p 
1,3         1,4         1,5         1,6 

1,7 

1,8 

1,9 

2,0 

1 

•     1,011 

1,012 

1,013 

1,014 

1,015 

1,016 

1,017 

1,018 

1,019 

1,020 

2 

1,022 

1,024 

1,026 

1,028 

1,030 

1,032 

1,034 

1,036 

1,038 

1,040 

3 

1,033 

1,036 

1,040 

1,043 

1,046 

1,049 

1,052 

1,055 

1,058 

1,061 

4 

1,045 

1,049 

1,053 

1,057 

1,061 

1,066 

1,070 

1,074 

1,078 

1,082 

5 

1,056 

1,061 

1,067 

1,072 

1,077 

1,083 

1,088 

1,093 

1,099 

1,104 

6 

1,068 

1,074 

1,081 

1,087 

1,093 

1,100 

1,107 

1,113 

1,120 

1,126 

7 

1,080 

1,087 

1,095 

1,102 

1,110 

1,118 

1,125 

1,133 

1,141 

1,149 

8 

1,091 

1,100 

1,109 

1,118 

1,126 

1,135 

1,144 

1,153 

1,163 

1,172 

9 

1,103 

1,113 

1,123 

1,133 

1,143 

1,154 

1.164 

1,174 

1,185 

1,195 

10 

1,116 

1,127 

1,138 

1,149 

1,161 

1,172 

1,184 

1,195 

1,207 

1,219 

11 

1,128 

1U40 

1,153 

1,165 

1,178 

1,191 

1,204 

1,217 

1,230 

1,243 

12 

1,140 

1,154 

1,168 

1,182 

1,196 

1,210 

1,224 

1,239 

"1,254 

1,268" 

13 

1,153 

1,168 

1,183 

1,198 

1,214 

1,229 

1.245 

1,261 

1,277 

1,294 

14 

1,166 

1,182 

1,198 

1,215 

1,232 

1,249 

1,266 

1,284 

1,302 

1,319 

15 

1,178 

1,196 

1,214 

1,232 

1,250 

1,269 

1,288 

1,307 

1,326 

1,346 

16 

1,191 

1,210 

1,230 

1,249 

1,269 

1,289 

1,310 

1,330 

1,352 

1,373 

17 

1,204 

1,225 

1,246 

1,267 

1,288 

1,310 

1,332 

1,354 

1,377 

1,400 

18 

1,218 

1,240 

1,262 

1,284 

1,307 

1,331 

1,355 

1,379 

1,403 

1,428 

19 

1,231 

1,254 

1,278 

1,302 

1,327 

1,352 

1,378 

1,404 

1,430 

1,457 

20 

1,245 

1,269 

1,295 

1,321 

1,347 

1,374 

1,401 

1,429 

1,457 

1,486 

21 

1,258 

1,285 

1,312 

1,339 

1,367 

1,396 

1,425 

1,455 

1,485 

1,516 

22 

1,272 

1,300 

1,329 

1,358 

1,388 

1,418 

1,449 

1,481 

1,513 

1,546 

23 

1,286 

11,316 

1,346 

1,377 

1,408 

1,441 

1,474 

1,507 

1,542 

1,577 

24 

1,300 

1,331 

1,363 

1,396 

1,429 

1,464 

1,499 

1,535 

1,571 

1,608 

25 

1,315 

1,347 

1,381 

1,416 

1,451 

1,487 

1,524 

1,562 

1,601 

1,641 

26 

1,329 

1,364 

1,399 

1,435 

1,473 

1,511 

1,550 

1,590 

1,631 

1,673 

27 

1,343 

1,380 

1,417 

1,456 

1,495 

1,535 

1,576 

1,619 

1,662 

1,707 

28 

1,358 

1,397 

1,436 

1,476 

1,517 

1,560 

1.603 

1,648 

1,694 

1,741 

29 

1,373 

1,413 

1,454 

1,497 

1,540 

1,585 

1,631 

1,678 

1,726 

1,776 

30 

1,388 

1,430 

1,473 

1,518 

1,563 

1,610 

1,658 

1,708 

1,759 

1,811 

35 

1,467 

1,518 

1,572 

1,627 

1,684 

1,743 

1,804 

1,867 

1,932 

2,000 

40 

1,549 

1,611 

1,676 

1,744 

1,814 

1,887. 

1,963 

2,041 

2,123 

2,208 

45 

1,636 

1,710 

1,788 

1,869 

1,954 

2,043 

2,135 

2,232 

2,333 

2,438 

50 

1,728 

1,816 

1,908 

2,004 

2,105 

2,211 

2,323 

2,440 

2,563 

2,692 

55 

1,825 

li,927 

2,035 

2,148 

2,268 

2,394 

2,527 

2,668 

2,816 

2,972 

60 

1,928 

2,046 

2,171 

2,303 

2,443 

2,592 

2,750 

2,917 

3,094 

3,281 

65 

2,036 

2,171 

2,315 

2.469 

2,632 

2,806 

2,991 

3,189 

3,399 

3,623 

70 

2,151 

2,305 

2,470 

2,646 

2,835 

3,038 

3,254 

3,486 

3,734 

4,000 

75 

2,272 

2,446 

2,635 

2,837 

3,055 

3,289 

3,541 

3,811 

4,103 

4,416 

80 

2,399 

2,597 

2,810 

3,041 

3,291 

3,560 

3,852 

4,167 

4,508 

to* 

85 

2,534 

2,756 

2,998 

3.260 

3,545 

3,854 

4,191 

4,556 

4,952 

5,383 

90 

2,677 

2,926 

3,198 

3,495 

.3,819 

4,173 

4,559 

4,981 

5,441 

5,943 

95 

2,827 

3,.106 

3,411 

3,746 

4,114 

4,518 

4,960 

5,446 

5,978 

6,562 

100 

2,986 

3,296 

3,639 

4,016 

4,432 

4,891 

5,396 

5,954 

6,568 

7,245 

110 

3,331 

3,714 

4,140 

4,615 

5,144 

5,732 

6,387 

7,116 

7,928 

8,831 

120 

3,717 

4,185 

4,711 

5,303 

5,969 

6,718 

7,560 

8,506 

9,570 

10,77 

APPENDIX 


161 


Years 
n 

2,1 

2,2 

Values  of  1.0pn,  where  p 
2,3         2,4         2,5         2,6 

2,7 

2,8 

2,9 

3,0 

1 

1,021 

1,022 

1,023 

1,024 

1.025 

1,026 

1,027 

1,028 

1,029 

1,030 

2 

1,043 

1,045 

1,047 

1,049 

1.051 

1,053 

1,055 

1,057 

1,059 

1,061 

3 

1,064 

1,068 

1,071 

1,074 

1,077 

1,080 

1,083 

1,086 

1,090 

1,093 

4 

1,087 

1,091 

1,095 

1.100 

1,104 

1,108 

1,113 

1,117 

1,121 

1,126 

5 

1,110 

1,115 

1,120 

1,126 

1,131 

1,137 

1,140 

1,148 

1,154 

1,159 

6 

1,133 

1,140 

1,146 

1,153 

1,160 

1,167 

1,173 

1,180 

1,187 

1,194 

7 

1,157 

1,165 

1,173 

1,181 

1,189 

1,197 

1,205 

1,213 

1,222 

1,230 

8 

1,181 

1,190 

1,200 

1,209 

1,218 

1,228 

1,238 

1,247 

1,257 

1,267 

9 

1,206 

1,216 

1,227 

1,238 

1,249 

1,260 

1,271 

1,282 

1,293 

1,305 

10 

1,231 

1,243 

1,255 

1,268 

1..280 

1,293 

1,305 

1,318 

1,331 

1,344 

11 

1,257 

1,271 

1,284 

1,297 

1,312 

1,326 

1,341 

1,355 

1,370 

1,384 

12 

1,283 

1,299 

1,314 

1.329 

1,345 

1,361 

1,377 

1,393 

1,409 

1,426 

13 

1,310 

1,327 

1,344 

1,361 

1,379 

1.396 

1,414 

1,432 

1,450 

1,468 

14 

1,338 

1.356 

1,375 

1,394 

1,413" 

1,433 

1,453 

1,472 

1,492 

1,513 

15 

1,366 

1,386 

1,407 

1,427 

1,448 

1,470 

1,492 

.  1,513 

1,536 

1,558 

16 

1,395 

1,417 

1,439 

1.462 

1,485 

1,508 

1,532 

1,556 

1,580 

1,605 

17 

1,424 

1,448 

1,472 

1,497 

1,522 

1,547 

1,573 

1,599 

1,626 

1,653 

18 

1,454 

1,480 

1,506 

1,533 

1.560 

1,587 

1,615 

1,644 

1,673 

1,702 

19 

1,484 

1,512 

1,541 

1,569 

1,599 

1,629 

1,659 

1,690 

1,721 

1,753 

20 

1,515 

1,545 

1,576 

1,607 

1,639 

1,671 

1,704 

1,737 

1,771 

1,806 

21 

1,547 

1,579 

1,612 

1,646 

1,680 

1,714 

1,750 

1,786 

1,823 

1,860 

22 

1,580 

1.614 

1,649 

1,685 

1/722 

1,759 

1,797 

1,836 

1,876 

1,916 

23 

1,613 

1,650 

1,687 

1,726 

1,765 

1,805 

1,846 

1,887 

1,930 

1,974 

24 

1,647 

1,686 

1,726 

1,767 

1,809 

1,852 

1,895 

1,940 

1,986 

2,033 

25 

1,681 

1,723 

1,766 

1,809 

1,854 

1,900 

1,947 

1,995 

2,044 

2,094 

26 

1,717 

1,761 

1.806 

1,853 

1,900 

1,949 

1,999 

2,050 

2,103 

2,157 

27 

1,753 

1,800 

1,848 

1,897 

1,948 

2,000 

2,053 

2,108 

2,164 

2,221 

28 

1,790 

1,839 

1,890 

1,943 

1,997 

2.052 

2,109 

2,167 

2.227 

2,288 

29 

1,827 

1,880 

1,934 

1,989 

2,046 

2,105 

2,165 

2,227 

2,291 

2,,357 

30 

1,865 

1,921 

1,978 

2,037 

2,098 

2,160 

2,224 

2,290 

2,358 

2,427 

35 

2,070 

2,142 

2,216 

2,294 

2,373 

2,456 

2,541 

2,629 

2,720 

2,814 

40 

2,296 

2,388 

2,483 

2,581 

2,685 

2.792 

2,903 

3,017 

3,138 

3,362 

45 

2,548 

2,663 

2,782 

2,907 

3,038 

3,174 

3,316 

3,465 

3,620 

3y782 

50 

2,827 

2,969 

3.117 

3,274 

3,437 

3,609 

3,789 

3,978 

4,176 

4,384 

55 

3,136 

3,310 

3,493 

3,686 

3,889 

4,103 

4,329 

4,567 

4,818 

5,082 

60 

3,480 

3,690 

3,913 

4,150 

4,400 

4,665 

4,946 

5,243 

5,558 

5,892 

65 

3,861 

4,115 

4,385 

4,672 

4,978 

5,304 

5,650 

6,019 

6.412 

6,830 

70 

4,284 

4.587 

4,912 

5,260 

5,632 

6,030 

6,455 

6,911 

7,397 

7,918 

75 

4,753 

5,115 

5,504 

5,923 

6,372 

6,856 

7,375 

7,934 

8.534 

9,179 

80 

5,273 

5,703 

6,167 

6,668 

7,210 

7,795 

8,426 

9,109 

9,845 

10,64 

85 

5,850 

6,358 

6,909 

7,508 

8,157 

8,862 

9,627 

10,46 

11,35 

12,34 

90 

6,491 

7,089 

7,741 

8.452 

9,229 

10,06 

11,00 

12,01 

13,10 

14,30 

95 

7,702 

7,904 

8,673 

9,517 

10,44 

11,46 

12,57 

13,78 

15,12 

16,58 

100 

7,991 

8,812 

9,718 

10,72 

11,81 

13,02 

14.36 

15,82 

17,44 

19,22 

110 

9,836 

10,83 

12,20 

13,58 

15,12 

16,60 

18,74 

20,86 

23.21 

25,83 

120 

12,11 

13.62 

15,31 

17,21 

19,36 

21,76 

24,46 

27,49 

30,89 

34,71 

162 


FOREST  VALUATION 


Years 
n 

3,1 

3,2 

Values  of  1 
3,3         3,4 

..Opn,  where  p 
3,5         3,6 

3,7 

3,8 

3,9 

4,0 

1 

1,031 

1,032 

1,033 

1,034 

1,035 

1,036 

1.037 

1,038 

1,039 

1,040 

2 

1,063 

1,065 

1,067 

1,070 

1,071 

1,073 

1,075 

1,077 

1.080 

1,082 

3 

1,096 

1,100 

1,102 

1,106 

1,109 

1,112 

1,115 

1,118 

1,122 

1,125 

4 

1,130 

1,134 

1,139 

1,143 

1,148 

1,152 

1,157 

1,161 

1,165 

1,170 

5 

1,165 

1,171 

1,176 

1,182 

1,188 

1,194 

1199 

1,205 

1,211 

1,217 

6 

1,201 

1,208 

1,215 

1.222 

1,229 

1,236 

1,244 

1,251 

1,258 

1,265 

7 

1,238 

1.247 

1,255 

1,264 

1,272 

1,281 

1,290 

1,298 

1,307 

1,316 

8 

1,277 

1,287 

1,297 

1,307 

1,317 

1,327 

1,337 

1,348 

1,358 

1,369 

9 

1,316 

1,328 

1,339 

1,351 

1,363 

1,375 

1.387 

1,399 

1,411 

1,423 

10 

1,357 

1,370 

1,384 

1,397 

1,411 

1,424 

1,438 

1,452 

1,466 

1,480 

11 

1,399 

1,414 

1,429 

1,445 

1,460 

1,476 

1,491 

1,507 

1,523 

1,539 

12 

1,443 

1,459 

1,476 

1,494 

1,511 

1,529 

1,547 

1,565 

1,583 

1,601 

13 

1,487 

1,506 

1,525 

1,545 

1,564 

1,584 

1.604 

1,624 

1,644 

1,665 

14 

.1,533 

1,554 

1,576 

1,597* 

1,619 

1,641 

1,663 

1,686 

1,709 

1,732 

15 

1,581 

1,604 

1,628 

1,651 

1,675 

1,700 

1,725 

1,750 

1,775 

1,801 

16 

1,630 

1,655 

1,681 

1,707 

1,734 

1,761 

1,788 

1,816 

1,844 

1,873 

17 

1,680 

1,708 

1,737 

1,766 

1,795 

1.824 

1,855 

1,885 

1,916 

1,948 

18 

1,733 

1,763 

1,794 

1,826 

1,857 

1,890 

1,924 

1,957 

1,991 

2,026 

19 

1.786 

1,819 

1.853 

1,888 

1,923 

1,958 

1.994 

2,031 

2,069 

2,107 

20 

1,842 

1,878 

1,915 

1,952 

1,990 

2,029 

2,068 

2,108 

2,149 

2,191f 

21 

1,899 

1,938 

1,978 

2,018 

2.059 

2.102 

2,145 

2,189 

2,233 

2,279 

22 

1,958 

2,000 

2,043 

2,087 

2,132 

2,177 

2,224 

2,272 

2,320 

2,370 

23 

2,018 

2,064 

2,110 

2,158 

2,206 

2,256 

2,306 

2,358 

2,411 

2,465 

24 

2,081 

2,130 

2,180 

2,231 

2,283 

2,337 

2,392 

2,448 

2,505 

2,563 

25 

2,145 

2,198 

2,252 

2,307 

2,363 

2,421 

'2,480 

2,541 

2,603 

2,666 

26 

2,212 

2,268 

2,326 

2,385 

2,446 

2,508 

2,572 

2,637 

2,704 

2,772 

27 

2,280 

2,341 

2,403 

2,467 

2,532 

2,599 

2,667 

2,737 

2,810 

2,883 

28 

2,351 

2,416 

2,482 

2,550 

2,620 

2,692 

2,766 

2,841 

2,919 

2,999 

29 

2,424 

2,493 

2,564 

2,637 

2,712 

2.789 

2,868 

2,949 

3,033 

3,119 

30 

2,499 

2,573 

2,649 

2,727 

2,807 

2,889 

2,974 

3,061 

3,151 

3,243 

35 

2,911 

3,012 

3.115 

3,223 

3,334 

3,448 

3,567 

3,689 

3,815 

3,94£ 

40 

3,391 

3,525 

3,664 

3,809 

3,959 

4,115 

4,277 

4,445 

4,620 

4,801 

45 

3,951 

4,127 

4,310 

4,50,2 

4,702 

4.911 

5,129 

5,357 

5,594 

5,841 

50 

4,602 

4,830 

5,070 

5,321 

5,585 

5,861 

6,151 

6,455 

6,776 

7,107  ' 

55 

5,361 

5,654 

5,964 

6,290 

6,633 

6,995 

7,376 

7,778 

8,201 

8,646 

60 

6,245 

6,619 

7,015 

7,434 

7,878 

8,348 

8,846 

9,373 

9,930 

10,52 

65 

7,275 

7,748 

8,251 

8,784 

9,357 

9,963 

10,61 

11,29 

12,02 

12,80 

70 

8,473 

9,069 

9,706 

10,39 

11,11 

11,89 

12,78 

13,59 

14,56 

15,57 

75 

9,872 

10,62 

11.42 

12,28 

13,20 

14,19 

15.26 

16,40 

17,63 

18,95 

80 

11,50 

12,43 

13,43 

14,51 

15,68 

16,94 

18,29 

19,76 

21,34 

23,05 

85 

13,40 

14.56 

15,80 

17,15 

18,62 

20,21 

21,94 

23,81 

25,84 

28,04 

90 

15,61 

17,03 

18,58 

20,27 

22,11 

24,12 

26,31 

28,69 

31,29 

34,12 

95 

18,18 

19,93 

21.85 

23,96 

26,26 

28,79 

31,55 

34,58 

37,89 

41,51 

100 

21,16 

23,33 

25,71  • 

28,32 

31,19 

34,36 

37,83 

41,66 

45,87 

50,50 

110 

28,74 

31,97 

35,57 

39,56 

44,00 

48.93 

54,41 

60,50 

67,25 

74,76 

120 

39,00 

43,81 

49,21 

55,27 

62,06 

69,69 

78,25 

87,84 

98,59 

110,7 

APPENDIX 


163 


Years 

n 

4,1 

4.2 

Values  of  l.Op",  where  p 
4,3         4,4         4,5         4,6 

4,7 

4,8 

4,9 

5,0 

1 

1,041 

1,042 

1,043 

1,044 

1,045 

1,046 

1,047 

1,048 

1,049 

1,050 

2 

1,083 

1,086 

1/088 

1,090 

1,092 

1,094 

1,096 

1,098 

1,100 

1,103 

3 

1,128 

1,131 

1,135 

1,138 

1,141 

1,145 

1,148 

1,151 

1,154 

1,158 

4 

1,174 

1.179 

1,184 

1,188 

1,193 

L,197 

1,202 

1,206 

1,211 

1,216 

5 

1,223 

1,228 

1,234 

1,240 

1,246 

1,252 

1,258 

1,264 

1,270 

1,276 

6 

1,273 

1,280 

1.287 

1,295 

1,302 

1,310 

1.317 

1,325 

1,333 

1,340 

7 

1,325 

1,334 

1,343 

1,352 

1,361 

1,370 

1,379 

1,389 

1,398 

1,407 

8 

1,379 

1,390 

1,401 

1,411 

1,422 

1,433 

1,444 

1,455 

1,466 

1,478 

9 

1,436 

1.448 

1,461 

1,473 

1,486 

1,499 

1,512 

1,532 

1,539 

1,551 

10 

1,495 

1,509 

1,524 

1,539 

1,553 

1,568 

1,583 

1,598 

1,614 

1,629 

11 

1,556 

1,573 

1,589 

1,610 

1,623 

1,640 

1,657 

1,675 

1,6-93 

1,710 

12 

1,620 

1.638 

1,657 

1,677 

1,696 

1,716 

1,735 

1,755 

1,776 

1,796 

13 

1,686 

1,707 

1,729 

1,750 

1,772 

1,794 

1,817 

1,840 

1,863 

1,886 

14 

1,755 

1,779 

1,803 

1,827 

1,852 

1,877 

1.902 

1,928 

1,954 

1,989 

15 

1,827 

1,854 

1,881 

1,908 

1,935 

1,963 

1,992 

2,020 

2,050 

2,079 

16 

1.902 

1932 

1,961 

1,992 

2,022 

2.054 

2,085 

2,117 

2,150 

2,183 

17 

1,980 

2,013 

2,046 

2,079 

2,113 

2,148 

2,183 

2,219 

2,255 

2,292 

18 

2,061 

2,097 

2,134 

2,171 

2,208 

2,247 

2.286 

2,326 

2,366 

2,407 

19 

2,146 

2,185 

2,225 

2,266 

2,308 

2,350 

2,393 

2,437 

2,482 

2,527 

20 

2,234 

2,277 

2,321 

2,366 

2,412 

2,458 

2,506 

2,554 

2,603 

2,653 

21 

2,325 

2,373 

2,421 

2,459 

2,520 

2,571 

2,624 

2,677 

2,731 

2,786 

22 

2,421 

2,472 

2,525 

2,579 

2,634 

2,690 

2,747 

2,805 

2,865 

2,925 

23 

2,520 

2,576 

2,634 

2,692 

2,752 

2,813 

2,876 

2,940 

3,005 

3.072 

24 

2,623 

2.684 

2,747 

2,811 

2,876 

2.943 

3,011 

3,081 

3,152 

3,225 

25 

2,731 

2,797 

2,865 

2,934 

3,005 

3,078 

3,153 

3,229 

3,307 

3,386 

26 

2,843 

2,915 

2.988 

3,064 

3,141 

3,220 

3.301 

3,384 

3,469 

3,556 

27 

2,959 

3,037 

3,117 

3,198 

3,282 

3,368 

3,456 

3,546 

3,639 

3,733 

28 

3,081 

S.164 

3,251 

3.339 

3,430 

3.523 

3,618 

3,716 

3,817 

3,920 

29 

3,207 

3,297 

3,390 

3,486 

3,584 

3,685 

3,788 

3,895 

4,004 

4,116 

30 

3,338 

3,436 

3.536 

3,640 

3,745 

3,854 

3,967 

4,082 

4,200 

4,322 

35 

4,081 

4,221  • 

4,365 

4,514 

4,667 

4,826 

4,990 

5,160 

5,335 

5,516 

40 

4,989 

5.1S5 

5,387 

5,598 

5,816 

6,043 

6,279 

6,523 

6,777 

7,040 

45 

6,099 

6,369 

6,650 

6,943 

7,248* 

7,567 

7,900 

8,246 

8,608 

8,985 

50 

7,257 

7,823 

8.208 

8,611 

9,033% 

9,475 

9.939 

10,43 

10,93 

11,47 

55 

9,116 

9,610 

10,13 

10,68 

11,26 

11,87 

12,51 

13,18 

13,89 

14,64 

60  ' 

11,15 

11.81 

12,51 

13..25 

14,03 

14,86 

15,73 

16,66 

17,64 

18,68 

65 

13,62 

14,50 

15,44 

16,43 

17,48 

18,60 

19,79 

21,06 

22,41 

23,84 

70 

16,66 

17,81 

19,05 

20,37 

21,78 

23,29 

24.  ,90 

26,63 

28,46 

30,43 

75 

20,36 

21,88 

23,52 

25,27 

27,15 

29,17 

31,33 

33,66 

36,16 

38,83 

80 

24,84 

26,88 

29,03 

31,34 

33,93 

36,52 

39,42 

42,55- 

45,93 

49,56 

85 

30,43 

33,02 

35,82 

38,86 

42,16 

45,73 

49,60 

53,79 

58,33 

63,25 

90 

37,20 

40,56 

44,22 

48,20 

52,54 

57.26 

62,41 

68,00 

74,10 

80,73 

95 

45,48 

4982 

54,58 

59,78 

65,47 

71,70 

78,51 

85,97 

94,12 

103,0 

100 

55,60 

61,20 

67,37 

74,14 

81,59 

89.78 

98,78 

108,7 

119,6 

131,5 

110 

83,10 

92,35 

102,6 

114,0 

126,7 

140,8 

156,4 

1*73,7 

192,9 

214,2 

120 

1-24,2 

139.4 

156,4 

175,4 

196,8 

220,7 

247,5 

277,5 

311,2 

348,9 

1 64 


ST  VALUATION 


Years 

H 

1,1 

5,2 

Values  of  l.Op",  where  p 
5,3         5,4         5,5         5,6 

5,7 

5,8 

5,9 

6,0 

1 

1,051 

1,052 

1,053 

1,054 

1,055 

1,056 

1,057 

1,058 

1,059 

1,060 

2 

1,105 

1,107 

1,109 

1,111 

1,113 

1,115 

1,117 

1,119 

1,122 

1,124 

3 

1,161 

1,164 

1,168 

1,171 

1,174 

1,178 

1,181 

1,184 

1,188 

1,191 

4 

1,220 

1,226 

1,230 

1,234 

1,239 

1,244 

1,248 

1,253 

1,258 

1,262 

5 

1,282 

1,289 

1,295 

1,301 

1,307 

1,313 

1,319 

1,326 

1,332 

1,338 

6 

1,348 

1.356 

1,363 

1,371 

1,379 

1,387 

1,395 

1,403 

1,411 

1,419 

7 

1,417 

1,423 

1,436 

1,445 

1,455 

1,464 

1,474 

1,484 

1,494 

1,504 

8 

1,489 

1,500 

1,512 

1,523 

1,535 

1,547 

1.558 

1,570 

1,582 

1,594 

9 

1,565 

1,578 

1,592 

1,604 

1,619 

1,633 

1,647 

1,661 

1,675 

1,689 

10 

1,645 

1,660 

1,676 

1,692 

1,708 

1,724 

1,741 

1,757 

1,774 

1,791 

11 

1,729 

1,747 

1,765 

1,783 

1,802 

1,821 

1,840 

1,859 

1,879 

1,898 

12 

1,817 

1,837 

1,859 

1,880 

1,901 

1,923 

1.945 

1,967 

1,990 

2,012 

13 

1,909 

1,933 

1,957 

1,981 

2,006 

2,031 

2,056 

2,081 

2,107 

2,133 

14 

2,007 

2,033 

2,061 

2,088 

2,116 

2,144 

2,173 

2,202 

2,231 

2,261 

15 

2,109 

2,139 

2,170 

2,201 

2,233 

2,265 

2,297 

2,330 

2,363 

2,397 

16 

2,216 

2,250 

2,285 

2,320 

2,355 

2,391 

2,428 

2,465 

2,502 

2,540 

17 

2,329 

2,367 

2,406 

2,445 

2,485 

2,525 

2,566 

2,608 

2,650 

2,693 

18 

2,448 

2.491 

2,534 

2,577 

2,621 

2,667 

2,712 

2,759 

2,806 

2,854 

19 

2,573 

2,620 

2,668 

2,716 

2,766 

2,815 

2,867 

2,919 

2,972 

3,026 

20 

2,704 

2,756 

2,809 

2,863 

2,918 

2,974 

3,030 

3,088 

3,147 

3,207 

21 

2,842 

2,900 

2,958 

3,018 

3,078 

3,140 

3,203 

3,267 

3,383 

3,400 

22 

2,987 

3,050 

3,115 

3,181 

3,248 

3,316 

3,386 

3,457 

3,530 

3,604 

23 

3,136 

3,209 

3,280 

3,352 

3,426 

3,502 

3,579 

3,657 

3,738 

3,829 

24 

3.300 

3,376 

3,454 

3,533 

3,615 

3,698 

3.783 

3,870 

3,958 

4,049 

25 

3,468 

3,551 

3,637 

3,724 

3,813 

3,905 

3,998 

4,094 

4,192 

4,292 

26 

3,645 

3>,V36 

3,830 

3,925 

4,023 

4,124 

4,226 

4,332 

4,439 

4,550 

27 

3,831 

3,930 

4.033 

4,137 

4,245 

4,354 

4,467 

4,583 

4,701 

4,822 

28 

4,026 

4,135 

4,246 

4,361 

4,478 

4,598 

4,722 

4,850 

4,978 

5,112 

29 

4,231 

4.350 

4,471 

4,596 

4,724 

4,856 

4,993 

5,130 

5,272 

5,418 

30 

4,447 

4..576 

4,708 

4,844 

4,984 

5,128 

5,275 

5,427 

5,583 

5,744 

35 

5.703 

5,896 

6,095 

6,301 

6,514 

6.734 

6.960 

7,195 

7,436 

7,686 

40 

7,313 

7,596 

7,891 

8,197 

8,513 

8,842 

9,184 

9,537 

9,905 

10,29 

45 

9,378 

9,788 

10,22 

10,66 

11,13 

11,61 

12,12 

12,64 

13,19 

13,77 

50 

12,03 

12,61 

13,23 

13,87 

14,54 

15,25 

15,99 

16,76 

17,57 

18,42 

55 

15,42 

16,25 

17,02 

18,04 

19,01 

20,02 

21,09 

22,23 

23,40 

24,65 

60 

19,78 

20,94 

22,17 

23,47 

24,84 

26,29 

27,83 

29,45 

31,17 

32,99 

65 

25,36 

26..9S 

28,70 

30,52 

32,46 

34,53 

36,72 

39,05 

41,52 

44,14 

70 

32,52 

34,76 

37,15 

39,71 

42,43 

45,34 

48,15 

51,76 

55,30 

59,08 

75 

41,71 

44,79 

48,10 

51,65 

55,46 

59,54 

63,92 

68,62 

73,66 

79,06 

80 

53,48 

57,71 

62,27 

67,18 

72,48 

78,18 

84,33 

90,96 

98,10 

105,8 

85 

68,59 

74,36 

80,62 

87,38 

94,73 

102,7 

111,3 

120,6 

130,6 

141,6 

90 

87,95 

95,81 

104,4 

113,7 

123,8 

134,8 

146,8 

159,9 

174,0 

189,5 

95 

112,8 

123,4 

135,1 

147,9 

161,8 

177,0 

193,7 

211,9 

231,8 

253,5 

100 

144,6 

159,1 

174,9 

192,3 

211,5 

232,5 

249,8 

280,9 

305,8 

339,3 

110 

237,9 

264.1 

293,2 

325,4 

361,2 

400,9 

444,9 

493,7 

547,7 

607,6 

120 

391,1 

438,4 

491,4 

550,7 

617,0 

691,3 

488,7 

867,5 

971,7 

1088 

APPENDIX 


165 


Years 
ft 

6,2 

6,4 

Values  of  1.0pn,  where  p 

6,6         6,8         7,0         7,2 

7,4 

7,6 

7,8 

8,0 

1 

1,062 

1,064 

1,066 

1,068 

1,070 

1,072 

1,074 

1,076 

1,078 

1,080 

2 

1,127 

1,132 

1,136 

1,141 

1,145 

1,149 

1,154 

1,158 

1,162 

1,166 

3 

1.198 

1,205 

1,211 

1,218 

1,225 

1,232 

1,239 

1,246 

1,253 

1,260 

4 

1,272 

1,282 

1,291 

1,301 

1,311 

1,321 

1.331 

1,341 

1,351 

1,361 

5 

1,351 

1,364 

1,377 

1,390 

1,403 

1,416 

1,429 

1,442 

1,456 

1,469 

6 

1,435 

1,451 

1,467 

1,484 

1,501 

1,518 

1,535 

1,552 

1,569 

1,587 

n 
i 

1.524 

1,544 

1,564 

1,585 

1,606 

1,627 

1,648 

1,670 

1,692 

1,714 

.    8 

1,618 

1,643 

1,668 

1,693 

1,718 

1,744 

1,770 

1,797 

1,824 

1,851 

9 

1,718 

1,748 

1,778 

1,808 

1,839 

1,870 

1,901 

1,933 

1,966 

1,999 

10 

1,825 

1,860 

1,895 

1,931 

1,967 

2,004 

2,042 

2,080 

2,119 

2,159 

11 

1.938 

1,979 

2,020 

2,062 

2,105 

2,149 

2,193 

2,238 

2,285 

2,326 

12 

2,058 

2,105 

2,153 

2,202 

2,252 

2,303 

2.355 

2,409 

2,463 

2,518 

13 

2,186 

2,240 

2,295 

2,352 

2,407 

2,469 

2,530 

2.592 

2,655 

2,720 

14 

2,321 

2.383 

2,447 

2,512 

2,579 

2,647 

2,716 

2,789 

2,862 

2,938 

15 

2,465 

2,535 

2,608 

2,683 

2,759 

2,838 

2,918 

3,001 

3,085 

3,172 

16 

2,618 

2,698 

2,781 

2,865 

2,952 

3,042 

3,133 

3,229 

3,326 

3,426 

17 

2,781 

2,870 

2,964 

3,060 

3,159 

3,261 

3,366 

3i,474 

3,585 

3,700 

18 

2,953 

3,055 

3,160 

3.268 

3,380 

3,496 

3,615 

3,738 

3,865 

3,996 

19 

3,136 

3,250 

3,368 

3,490 

3,617 

3,747 

3,882 

4,022 

4,166 

4,316 

20 

3,330 

3,458 

3,590 

3,728 

3,870 

4,017 

4,170 

4,328 

4,491 

4,661 

21 

3,537 

3,679 

3,827 

3,981 

4,141 

4,306 

4,478 

4,657 

4,842 

5,034 

22 

3,756 

3,915 

4,080 

4,252 

4,431 

4,616 

4,810 

5,010 

5,219 

5,437 

23 

3.989 

4,165 

4,349 

4,541 

4,741 

4,949 

5,165 

5,391 

5,627 

5,872 

24 

4,236 

4.432 

4,636 

4,850 

5,072 

5,305 

5.548 

5,801 

6,065 

6,341 

25 

4,499 

4,716 

4,942 

5,180 

5,428 

5,687 

5,958 

6,213 

6,538 

6,849 

26 

4,778 

5.018 

5,269 

5,532 

5,807 

6,096 

6,399 

6,716 

7,048 

7,396 

27 

5.074 

5,339 

5,616 

5,908 

6,214 

6,535 

6,873 

7,227 

7,598 

7,988 

28 

5,389 

5,680 

5,987 

6,310 

6,649 

7,005 

7,381 

7,776 

8,191 

8,627 

29 

5.723 

6,044 

6,382 

6,739 

6,794 

7,510 

7,927 

8,367 

8,830 

9,317 

30 

6,078 

6,431 

6,803 

7,197 

7,612 

8,051 

8,514 

9,003 

9,518 

10,06 

35 

8.210 

8,769 

9,365 

10,00 

10,68 

11,40 

12,17 

12,99 

13,86 

14,79 

40 

11,09 

11,96 

12,89 

13,90 

14,98 

16,14 

17.39 

18,73 

20,17 

21,73 

45 

14,98 

16,31 

17,75 

19,31 

21,00 

22,85 

24,84 

27,01 

29,37 

31,92 

50 

20,24 

22.24 

24,43 

26,82 

29,46 

32,34 

35,50 

38,96 

42,75 

46,90 

55 

27,34 

30,33 

33,62 

37,28 

41,32 

45,79 

50,73 

56,19 

62,24 

68,92 

60 

36,94 

41,35 

46,29 

51,79 

57,95 

64,82 

72,49 

81,05 

90,60 

101,3 

65 

49,90 

56,39 

63,71 

71,97 

81,27 

91,76 

103,5 

116,4 

131,9 

149,1 

70 

67,41 

76,90 

87,70 

100,0 

114,0 

129,9 

148,0 

168,6 

192,0 

218,6 

75 

91,06 

104,9 

120,7 

139,0 

159,9 

183,9 

211,5 

243.2 

279,5 

321,2 

80 

123,0 

143,Q 

166,2 

193,1 

224,2 

260,4 

302,2 

350,7 

406',9 

472rO 

85 

166.2 

195,0 

228,8 

268,3 

314,5 

368,6 

431,9 

505,8 

592,4 

693,5 

90 

224,5 

265,9 

314,9 

372,8 

441,1 

521,8 

617,1 

729,6 

862,4 

1019 

95 

303,3 

362.6 

433,5 

517,9 

618,7 

738,8 

881,9 

1052 

1256 

1497 

100 

409,7 

494,5 

596,7 

719,7 

867,7 

1046 

1260 

1518 

1828 

2200 

i66 


FOREST  VALUATION 


Years 
n 

8,2 

8,4 

Values  of  l.Op",  where  p 

8,6         8,8         9,0         9,2 

9,4 

9,6 

9,8 

10 

1 

1,082 

1,084 

1,086 

1,088 

1.090 

1,092 

1,094 

1,096 

1,098 

1,100 

2 

1,171 

1,175 

1,179 

1,184 

1,188 

1,193 

1,197 

1,201 

1,206 

1,210 

3 

1,267 

1,274 

1,281 

1,288 

1,295 

1,302 

1,309 

1,317 

1.324 

1,331 

4 

1,371 

1,381 

1,391 

1,401 

1,412 

1,422 

1,432 

1,443 

1,454 

1,464 

5 

1,483 

1,497 

1,510 

1,525 

1.539 

1,552 

1,567 

1,582 

1,596 

1,611 

6 

1,605 

1,623 

1,641 

1,659 

1,677 

1,696 

1,714 

1,733 

1,752 

1,772 

7 

1,736 

1,759 

1,782 

1,805 

1,828 

1,852 

1,876 

1.900 

1,924 

1,949 

8 

1,878 

1,907 

1,935 

1,964 

1,993 

2,022 

2,052 

2,082 

2,113 

2,144 

9 

2.033 

2,067 

2,101 

2,136 

2,172 

2,208 

2,245 

2,282 

2,320 

2,358 

10 

2,199 

2,240 

2,282 

2,324 

2,367 

2,411 

2,456 

2,501 

2,547 

2,594 

11 

2,380 

2,429 

2,478 

2,529 

2,581 

2,633 

2,687 

2,741 

2,797 

2,853 

12 

2.575 

2,632 

2,691 

2,751 

2,813 

2.875 

2,939 

3,004 

3,071 

3,139 

13 

2,786 

2,854 

2,923 

2,994 

3,066 

3,133 

3,215 

3,293 

3,372 

3,452 

14 

3,014 

3,093 

3,174 

3,257 

3,337 

3,429 

3,518 

3,609 

3,702 

3,798 

15 

3,262 

3,353 

3,447 

3,544 

3,643 

3,744 

3,848 

3,955 

4,065 

4,177 

16 

3.529 

3,635 

3,744 

3,855 

3,970 

4.089 

4,210 

4,334 

4,463 

4,595 

17 

3,818 

3,940 

4,066 

4,195 

4,328 

4,465 

4,606 

4,751 

4,901 

5,055 

18 

4,131 

4,271 

4.415 

4,564 

4,417 

4,875 

5,038 

5,207 

5,381 

5,560 

19 

4,470 

4,630 

4,795 

4,965 

5,142 

5,324 

5,512 

5,707 

5,908 

6,116 

20 

4,837 

5,019 

5,207 

5,402 

5,605 

5,814 

6,030 

6,254 

6,487 

6,728 

21 

5,233 

5,440 

5,655 

5,878 

6,109 

6,349 

6,597 

6,855 

7,123 

7,400 

22 

5,662 

5,897 

6,141 

6,395 

6,659 

6,933 

7.217 

7,513 

7,821 

8,140 

23 

6,127 

6,393 

6,669 

6,958 

7,258 

7,571 

7,896 

8,235 

8,587 

8,954 

24 

6,629 

6,930 

7,243 

7,570 

7.911 

8,267 

8,638 

9,025 

9,429 

9,850 

25 

7,173 

7,512 

7,866 

8,236 

8-,623 

9,028 

9,450 

9,892 

10,35 

10,84 

26 

7,761 

8,143 

8,542 

8.961 

9,399 

9,858 

10,34 

10.84 

11,37 

11,92 

27 

8,397 

8,827 

9,277 

9,750 

10,25 

10,77 

11,31 

11,88 

12,48 

13,11 

28 

9,086 

9,568 

10,08 

10,61 

11.17 

11,76 

12,37 

13,02 

13,71 

14,42 

29 

9,831 

10,37 

10,94 

11,54 

12,17 

12,84 

13,54 

14,27 

15,05 

15,86 

30 

10,64 

11,24 

11,88 

12,56 

13,27 

14,03 

14,81 

15,64 

16,52 

17,45 

35 

15,78 

16,83 

17,95 

19,14 

20,41 

21,77 

23,21 

24,73 

26,37 

28,10 

40 

231.39 

25,19 

27,11 

29,19 

31.41 

33,80 

36,37 

39,12 

42,08 

45,26 

45 

34,69 

37,70 

40,96 

44,49 

48,33 

52,48 

56,99 

61,87 

67,16 

72,89 

50 

51,45 

56,43  • 

61,87 

67.83 

74,36 

81,50 

89.30 

97,84 

107,2 

117,4 

55 

76,30 

84,45 

93,46 

103,4 

114,4 

126,6 

140,0 

154,7 

171,1 

189,1 

60 

113x2 

126,4 

141,2 

157,7 

176,0 

196,5 

219,3 

244,7 

273,0 

304,5 

65 

167,8 

189,2 

213,3 

240,4 

270,8 

305,1 

343,7 

387,0 

435,7 

490,4 

70 

248,8 

283,2 

322,2 

366.5 

416,7 

473,8 

538.5 

612,0 

695,3 

789,8 

75 

369,0 

423,8 

486.7 

558,7 

641,2 

735,7 

843,9 

967,8 

1110 

1272 

80 

'547,3 

634,4 

735,2 

851,8 

986,6 

1142 

1323 

1531 

1771 

2048 

APPENDIX  167 

C.     Suggestions  for  problems  for  use  in  teaching. 

The  following  problems  are  offered  here  merely  as  suggestions. 
Some  practice  in  the  use  of  the  analyses  and  formulae  has  been 
found  necessary  to  fix  these  matters  in  the  minds  of  the  students. 

1.  Capital  Co  =  $50,  p  =  3%;  what  does  this  capital  grow 
into  in  7,  19,  37,  and  83  years? 

2.  Capital  now  is  $500;  has  been  out  at  2l/2%  compound  in- 
terest; what  was  it  worth  17,  43,  and  120  years  ago? 

3.  $140  grew  into  $190  in  17  years;  what  is  i.op17  and  what 
is  p? 

4.  -  A  tree  contains  430  cubic  feet ;  it  is  growing  at  1.2%  ;  what 
is  the  growth  for  5  years  in  cubic  feet  ? 

5.  A  tree  now  has  430  cubic  feet ;  23  years  ago  it  had  375  ;  at 
what  p  did  it  grow,  wThat  is  i.opn  in  this  case? 

400 

6.  Schneider's  formula  says:  pv=-  for  older  timber  (D 

nD 

being  dbh  and  n  the  number  of  rings  in  outer  one  inch).  Suppose 
stand  of  timber  has  40,000  cubic  feet;  average  D  21  inches,  and  n 
12 ;  at  what  rate  is  this  stand  growing,  what  is  the  value  of  five  years 
growth  at  7  cents  per  cubic  foot  ? 

7.  A  locomotive  sets  fire  to  a  stand  of  pine  planted  25  years 
ago ;  it  cost  10  dollars  an  acre  to  plant ;  what  is  the  loss  if  only 
planting  expense  and  interest  at  3%  is  counted? 

8.  A  stand  is  now  35  years  old.     We  expect  it  to  be  worth 
$350  when  80  years  old;  what  is  its  present  value;  p  — 3%,  and  no 
expenses  figured. 

9.  A  farm  rents  at  100  dollars,  clear,  over  and  above  expenses. 
Rate  per  cent  3%  and  also  2%.    What  is  the  value  of  the  farm  and 
what  is  the  value  of  25  years  use  of  it? 

10.  A  forest  property  is  worth  $10,000,  based  on  income,  but 
it  can  not  be  sold  until  15  years  from  now ;  the  property  is  used  and 
no  change  is  expected.    What  is  its  value  today  at  2%  and  at  4%  ? 

11.  A  note  for  $500  at  4%  is  due  in  7  years;  it  has  run  3 
years ;  all  interest  and  capital  to  be  paid  in  at  end  of  7  years.   What 
is  the  note  worth  now  to  a  man  who  is  willing  to  take  3%  on  his 
money  ? 

12.  A  stand  of  timber  contains  550  cords ;  it  contained  470, 
10  years  ago;  what  was  pv  for  this  time?    If  this  timber  now  brings 
$4.50  per  100  cubic  feet  but  brought  only  $3.75  per  100  cubic  feet, 
10  years  ago,  what  is  pq,  quality  growth,  in  per  cent?     If  there  is 
no  price  growth,  what  is  pf,  i.  e.,  the  growth  in  value  of  this  stand? 


1 68  FOREST  VALUATION, 

13.  What  is  the  growth,  in  quality  in' per  cent,  for  each  decade 
which  will  keep  the  growth  in  value  constant  between  the  ages  40 
and  100  years  in  spruce,  site  II,  as  in  Schwappach  tables? 

14.  Eight  hundred  acres  of  timber  is  cut  over  every  10  years 
and  nets  $12  per  acre  at  each  cut.     Expenses  per  acre:  taxes   15 
cents,  protection  10  cents.     What  is  the  value  of  the  forest  at  2% 
and  at  3%  ?    What  is  100  years  lease  worth  if  the  last  cut  came  6 
years  ago? 

15.  One  hundred  acres  of  land  may  be  farmed.     At  farming 
it  brings  75  cents  per  acre  net.    If  planted  to  pine  and  r  =  80  years ; 
Yr=6o  cords  at  $3;  C  — $10;  €==25  cents;  p  =  4,  3,  and  2% — 
which  use  is  more  profitable? 

1 6.  Six  thousand  acres  of  North  Carolina  pinery  cut  over  lands 
bought  at  $5  per  acre ;  expenses  per  acre :  taxes  10  cents,  protection 
5  cents,  p  =  3%  ;  what  is  Fc  in  25  years?     If  timber  is  $6  per  M. 
feet,  how  much  must  one  get  to  make  interest  and  expenses,  and 
leave  the  forest  as  good  as  when  bought? 

17.  Mountain   lands   in    Pennsylvania;   can   return   every    15 
years  for  6  cords  of  hardwood  stuff,  mostly  coppice,  worth  $2  per 
cord  on  stump.    Taxes  5  cents  per  acre ;  no  other  charges ;  what  is 
the  value  of  the  woods  at  3%  ? 

18.  A  farmer  has  60  acres  inferior  lands ;  he  paid  $18  an  acre. 
He  has  rented  this  at  $i  per  acre  for  pasture.     Expenses  per  acre: 
taxes  15  cents,  fences  10  cents,  p  =  3%.     He  plants  up  30  acres  to 
hardwoods.   C  — $10,  first  cut  when  15  years  old.    How  much  must 
he  cut  if  income  is  to  be  as  good  as  at  pasture  use,  if  he  values  stuff 
at  $2  per  cord? 

19.  One  hundred  acres  coppice ;  non-agricultural  land,  can  be 
cut  every  20  years  for  15  cords  of  stuff,  last  cut  9  years  ago,  stump- 
age  now  $i  per  cord.     Expected  rise  in  market  price  20  cents  per 
cord  for  each  of  the  next  5  rotations ;  after  this  constant.    What  is 
this  woods  worth  at  3%  ? 

Y        20.     Four  thousand  acres  of  pine  woods  in  North  Carolina  can 
^  Y   be  cut  over  every  15  years  for  5  M.  feet."    Last  cut  7  years  ago. 
What  yearly  payment  or  annuity  can  a  trust  company  pay  if  they 
rate  money  at  3%  ? 

21.  One  thousand  acres  of  coppice  woods  in  Pennsylvania  have 
cut  15  cards  every  25  years  for  iron  furnace;  stumpage  $1.50.  Plan 
is  to  concert  into  spruce  for  pulp  on  50  year  rotation.  If  Yr  =  3O 
cords  at  %;t£=$io;  thin.  =  o;  taxes  in  first  case  15  cents,  in  new 
case  i6%  of  stumpage  as  yield  tax ;  protection  and  care  =  10  cents ; 
pz^3%.  How  do  the  two  compare? 


APPENDIX  J  69 

22.  Spruce  forest. 

a.  Present  practice :     Natural   reproduction,   takes    10  years, 
requires  no  artificial  help ;  rotation  90  years,  i.  e.,  90  from  end  of  one 
reproduction  to  end  of  next;  thinning  needed  early,  15  years  after 
reproduction  is  started,  costs  $5  an  acre. 

Second  thinning  costs  $2  per  acre  at  age  of  25. 

Third  thinning  at  40  years  brings  $5  net. 

Fourth  thinning  at  60  years  brings  $20  net. 

Fifth  thinning  at  80  years  brings  $40  net. 

Yr  at  90  years  would  be  $600  but  owing  to  extra  cost  of  logging 
is  only  $560. 

e  is  $i  per  acre  and  year,  including  taxes;  p  =  3%.  What  is 
Sehere? 

b.  Plan  is  now  to  change  this  as  follows : 

Plant  5  year  transplants  space  6x6;  plants  cost  $3  per  M,  set- 
ting costs  $5  per  M. 

First  thinning  at  20  years  pays  expense. 

Second  thinning  at  40  years  pays  $20. 

Third  thinning  at  60  years  pays  $40. 

Fourth  thinning  at  80  years  pays  $iop. 

Yr  should  be  $600  but  heavy  thinning  reduces  volume  but  raises 
quality  so  that  we  still  have  $540,  saving  $40  on  cost  of  logging. 

e  and  p  same  as  before.  What  is  the  new  Se,  and  how  does  this 
compare  to  the  old  plan? 

23.  Beech   forest,   site   II,   is  not   satisfactory  as   to   income. 
Make  concrete  case  from  Schwappach  to  show  how  this  would  work 
out  if  changed  to  spruce  and  to  pine.    Put  p  —  3 %,  e  =  $i,  C  =  $10. 

24.  State  of  Michigan  has  been  selling  land  inclusive  of  some 
growing  stock  at  $i  per  acre.    If  put  in  pine,  C  =  $10,  e  =  50  cents, 
p  =  2%  and  r^=8o  years,  how  much  pine  must  the  state  cut  per 
acre  to  beat  the  $i,  with  stumpage  at  $10  per  M? 

25.  Work  out  Se  at  2,  4  and  5%  for    spruce,  pine  and  oak, 
all  for  site  II;  C  =  $io,  e  =  $i,  and  r  =  4O,  60,  80,  100  and  120 
years. 

Yr  and  thinnings  as  by  Schwappach.    Tabulate. 

26.  What  is  Se  in  coppice,  rotation  25  years ;  Yr  20  cords  at 
$2 ;  thinnings  cover  expenses  and  taxes,  planting  costs  $2  in  each- 
rotation,  i.  e.,  at  each  cut;  p  — 3%.    Is  this  really  Se? 

27.  Fe,  pine  in  North  Carolina  ready  to  cut  over*  n&w,  for 
10  M.  feet  at  $6,  can  return  every  20  years  ;  e  —  50  cents,  soil  =  $5, 

=        .     Find  Fe. 


1 70  FOREST  VALUATION 

28.  What  is  °-<r-'>Gc  and  °-<r-OGe  in  Spruce,  Yr  and  thinnings 
as  by  Schwappach,  site  II,  r  =  8o  years  and  100  years,  e  =  $i,  p  = 
3%,  Sc  =  $2o. 

29.  What  is  Fc  and  Fe  in  the  above  case  if  Sc  is  replaced  by 
Se  in  the  calculation? 

30.  If  the  state  of  Michigan  wanted  to  go  into  forestry  and 
establish  one  million  acres  of  forest  in  regulated  condition  what  in- 
vestment, i.  e.,  what  is  Fc.  if  :   soil  =  $5  per  acre  ;  C  =  $10  per  acre ; 
e  —  50  cents  ;  p  =  2%;  r  =  So  y  ;  Yr  =  $200 ;  thinnings  neglected. 
What  is  Fc  if  Se  is  substituted  and  what  is  Fe  then? 

31.  What  rate  of  interest  is  made  in  the  following  case:  stand 
at  80  years  worth  $350;  at  60  worth  $200,  with  land  worth  $10  an 
acre,  e  — 50  cents  and  rate  of  interest  3%.     Explain  principle  in- 
volved, and  write  out  formula. 

32.  If   C==$TO,    6  =  50   cents,   p  =  3%,    soil  =  $io,    r  =  8o 
years,  and  Yr  =  $3OO,  what  pf  is  made  here  in  raising  the  crop? 

33.  A  lumber  company  bought  10  sections  of  timber  10  years 
ago  at  $15  per  acre,  land  and  timber;  p  =  5%  ;  will  cut  12  M.  feet 
per  acre ;  expenses  per  acre,  assessment  at  J^  cost  value ;  tax  rate  = 
12  per  i ,000;  protection,  etc.,  —  5  cents  ;  no  net  growth,  no  fires,  etc. 
losses  so  far.    What  is  Fc  now? 

What  is  Fe  if  the  cut  expected  is  12  M.  feet  at  $6  and  the 
company  expects  to  get  at  this  timber  in  8  years?  Expenses  to  con- 
tinue uniform.  How  does  the  Fc  and  Fe  compare  did  they  pay 
too  much? 

34.  If  average  stumpage  costs  $5  per  M.  feet  what  must  the 
lumber  be  worth  which  will  be  cut  in  40  years  from  now  if :   milling 
=  $4 ;  logging  =  $6 ;  taxes  5  cents  per  M.  feet ;  protection  =  i  cent 
per  M.  feet;  pr=5%;  and  land  in  40  years  to  be  worth  $10;  to 
justify  buying  this  now  at  $5  per  M.  feet. 

35.  A  saw  mill  costs:  for  buildings,  $10,000,  life  of  this  30 
years,  wreckage  value  $1,000;  for  steam  engines,  etc.,  $15,000,  life 
15  years,  wreckage  value  $1,000;  saw  mill  machinery  $25,000,  life 
10  years,  wreckage  value  $3,000.     What  is  depreciation  cost  in  this 
mill  per  year,  if  p  —  5%  ? 

36.  A  lumber  company  has  25  years  timber  on  hand.     It  cuts 
20  million  feet ;  lands  cut  10  M.  feet  per  acre.     They  paid  $6  per 
acre.    As  fast  as  lands  are  cut  over  they  sell  for  $i  to  a  realty  com- 
pany. They  pay  20  cents  tax  an  acre,  and  also  5  cents  for  protection. 
Interest  rate  =5%.     What  does  the  stumpage  cost  them  on  their 
20  million  feet  per  year? 


APPENDIX  171 

37.  A  lumber  company  bought  30  thousand  acres  of  timber 
lands;  which  cut  12  M.  per  acre;  no  net  growth ;  they  paid  $10  an 
acre,  build  a  saw  mill,  planing  mill  and  other  buildings  at  a  cost  of 
$150,000,  and  buy  logging  equipment  at  $50.000  more.  They  log 
for  $6  and  mill  for  $4  which  includes  all  expenses.  They  get  $18, 
per  M.  feet  on  board  car  at  mill ;  cut  20  million  per  year.  Taxes  on 
y2  value  at  10  per  1,000,  interest  at  5%  ;  depreciation  and  replace- 
ment as  follows : 

Xone  for  buildings,  the  repairs  are  paid  by  milling  costs. 

All  machinery  is  replaced  once  during  the  entire  cut.  Buildings 
cost  new  $60,000  and  are  worth  at  end  $10,000.  Machinery  at  start 
$90,000,  at  end  $10,000.  The  logging  outfit  is  kept  up  by  logging- 
charge  of  $6. 

a.  What  is  the  yearly  depreciation  on  buildings?     What  on 
machinery  ? 

b.  What  does  the  20  million  feet  lumber  cost  them  and  what 
is  their  net  income  per  year? 

c.  What  is  the  expectation  value  of  the  whole  enterprise  at 
start  and  after  7  years  cut? 

d.  If  a  fire  reduces  their  forest  by  5  years  cutting  what  is  the 
damage  to  the  company? 


UNIVERSITY  OF  CALIFORNIA  LIBRARY 
BERKELEY 

Return  to  desk  from  which  borrowed. 
This  book  is  DUE  on  the  last  date  stamped  below. 


FEB  IB  194* 


LD  21-100m-9,'47(A5702sl6)476 


U.C.  BERKELEY  LIBRARIES 


UNIVERSITY  OF  CALIFORNIA  LIBRARY