Skip to main content

Full text of "More on the use of beta in regulatory proceedings"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  Of 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

£[  URBANA-CHAMPAiSri 

STACXS 


s o— 


(A1.5)     (1  "  *'f  y  -  a  +  (1  -  «JB)w  x.  +  £ 
(1  -  8B^)   C  u  c    c 

t 
where  a  and  w  have  been  added  to  correct  for  the  fact  that  a  in  (A1.4) 

and  a  in  (A1.3)  night  be  of  different  scale  and  correlated.   Next 

multiplying  both  sides  of  A1.5  thru  by  -p. t  '   we  obtain 

qj.  —  9  a) 

and  assuming  (1  -  <j>'3)  cancels  with  (1  -  4>E)  (empirically  we  found  these 

q 

factors   to  be  approximately  equal   )   we   obtain  the   final  model 

(A1.7)  yt  -  ««   +  (1  -   3B4)wQxt   +   [I  I   gfcl    lt 

which   can  be  written  in  more   conventional   form 


(A1.8)  yt   =   o'    +  w0xt  +  ewQxt_4   +  *'Bnt_1  +  9at_4   +  i£ 

where  n     is   the  noise   series. 

The   result   is  identical  to  AMI  but   the    term   9w..x_    ,    is  added   to   the 

0    t-4 

model. 


M/B/175 


Faculty  Working  Papers 


MORE  ON  THE  USE  OF  BETA  IN  REGULATORY  PROCEEDINGS 

Charles  M.  Linke,  Professor,  Department  of 

Finance 
John  E.  Gilster,  Jr.,  Assistant  Professor, 

Department  of  Finance 

#691 


College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 

University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 


-  <fr'B) 


'  '□^  <•- 


and  assuming  (1  -  $'3)  cancels  wit 

Q 

factors  to  be  approximately  equal 


(A1.7)  7t   =  a'    +   (1  -   6B*)v0xt 


which  can  be  written  in  more  convei 


+ 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPERS 
College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 
July  27,  1980 


MORE  ON  THE  USE  OF  BETA  IN  REGULATORY  PROCEEDINGS 

Charles  M.  Linke,  Professor,  Department  of 

Finance 
John  E.  Gilster,  Jr.,  Assistant  Professor, 

Department  of  Finance 

#691 


Summary 

This  paper  analyzes  the  process  by  which  security  prices  adjust 
to  new  information  and  shows  that  the  adjustment  process  itself  can 
lead  to  temporary  non-stationarity  of  security  return  distributions. 
The  paper  illustrates  the  serious  effect  this  can  have  on  security 
returns  and  argues  that  the  price  adjustment  process  can  have  a 
similar  effect  on  expost  measurements  of  beta.   Some  implications  for 
utility  rate  regulation  are  discussed. 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/moreonuseofbetai691link 


MORE  ON  THE  USE  OF  BETA  IN  REGULATORY  PROCEEDINGS 
1.  Introduction 

Modern  portfolio  theory  is  sometimes  used  to  measure  the  risk  per- 
ceptions of  equity  investors  and  thereby  to  determine  an  appropriate 
allowed  rate  of  return  for  a  utility.   Recent  articles  in  this  Journal 
(Breen  and  Lerner,  1972;  Myers,  1972a,  1972b;  and  Pettway,  1978)  have 
questioned  whether  utility  betas  display  sufficient  stationarity  for  the 
return  estimation  logic  of  modern  portfolio  theory  to  be  operationally 
useful  in  rate  regulatory  proceedings. 

Blume  (1971,  1975),  Levy  (1971),  Porter  and  Ezzel  (1974),  Pettway 
(1978),  Francis  (1980),  and  others  have  reported  significant  non-sta- 
tionarity  in  measured  beta.  These  authors  have  generally  argued  that 
the  non-stationarity  of  measured  beta  is  due  to  changes  in  the  under- 
lying "true"  beta.  This  hypothesized  non-stationarity  of  "true"  beta 
has  been  shown  to  generate  unusual  measured  betas  at  the  individual 
firm  level.  Brigham  and  Crum  (1977)  have  used  simulated  data  to  demon- 
strate that  under  extreme  conditions  a  drop  in  the  price  of  a  security 
resulting  from  an  increase  in  true  beta  could  actually  cause  measured 
beta  to  decline  temporarily.  Instability  in  measured  beta  as  well  as 
the  possibility  of  such  divergent  movements  between  "true"  and  measured 
beta  have  caused  Pettway  (1978),  Breen  and  Lerner  (1972),  Brigham  and 
Crum  (1977),  Carleton  (1978),  and  others  to  suggest  the  £  framework,  may 
not  provide  a  feasible  approach  to  rate  regulation. 

This  paper  will  point  out  that  the  process  by  which  securities  ad- 
just to  dramatic,  unanticipated,  new  information  can  produce  misleading 
estimates  of  systematic  risk.  Section  2  presents  a  theoretical 


-2- 

description  of  the  phenomena.  Section  3  suggests  this  phenomena  as  a 
possible  explanation  for  the  beta  non-stationarity  in  the  utility  industry 
observed  by  Pettway  and  the  beta  non-stationarity  surrounding  stock  splits 
observed  by  Bar-Yosef  and  Brown.  Concluding  observations  comprise  the 
final  section. 

2.  Measured  Beta  and  A  Variability  Phenomenon 

Modern  portfolio  theory  does  not  require  the  0  measure  of  security 
risk  be  stable  over  time.   Indeed,  a  firm's  perceived  systematic  risk 
characteristics  and  hence  its  g  can  be  expected  to  vary  with  strategic 
and  tactical  management  decisions  made  in  response  to  changing  product 
and  factor  market  conditions. 

This  paper  will  point  out  that  the  price  adjustment  process  by  which 
securities  adapt  to  new  information  can  produce  misleading  beta  measure- 
ments . 

The  potentially  bizarre  nature  of  this  adjustment  phenomena  is  best 
illustrated  by  its  effect  on  security  returns.  Consider  a  firm  that  ex- 
periences a  shift  in  its  systematic  risk  from  .5  to  .75.  If  the  risk  free 
rate,  P-,  is  6.0%  and  the  expected  return  on  the  market,  E(PO,  is  12%, 
then  investors  pre  shift  required  return  is  9.0%,  while  the  post-shift 
required  return  is  10.5%.  Assume  for  convenience  this  firm  earns  9.0%  on 
its  $100  book  value  per  share,  pays  out  all  earnings,  and  the  pre  6 
shift  market  price  of  the  stock  equals  book  value.  The  equilibrium 
holding  period  return,  R  ,  in  the  (3  pre-shift  period  would  be 

r     .  ?t  "  Pt-1  *  Dt   $100  -  $100  +  $9  _   n„ 

e  Pfc  ,  $100      "  y'U7° 

pre        t-1 


-3- 


where  P  is  price  in  time  t,  and  D  is  dividend  in  time  t.   Assuming  no 
change  in  expected  return  on  book  value,  the  only  way  the  $9  annual  divi- 
dends can  provide  the  required  6  post  shift  return  of  10.5%  is  for  the 
price  to  decline  to  $85.71.  This  will  produce  an  observed  annual  rate  of 
return,  R  ,  during  the  adjustment  period  of 

_  _  $85.71  -  $100.00  +  $9.00  _  .  0Q_ 
o  "  $100.00       "  ~5'23A   ' 

An  increase  in  required  return  has  produced  a  temporary  decrease  in  re- 
turn! Such  price  adjustments  are  also  triggered  by  changes  in  earnings 
expectations  or  the  prevailing  risk-return  tradeoff. 

The  effect  of  the  adjustment  process  on  beta  is  more  subtle.  The 
effect  can  be  analyzed  by  expressing  the  total  observable  return,  R  ,  as 
the  sum  of  an  equilibrium  return,  R  ,  and  an  adjustment  return,  R_,  or 

R  =  R  +  R  .  (1) 

o    e    a 

Beta   is   equal    to 

6o   =   Cov(W/aM  (2) 

-    [E(RoV    -EO^EOgi/c*    .  (3) 

Expressing  R  as  a  linear  function  of  R  yields 

R  =  a_  +  a,R  +  e  (4) 

a    0    1  e 

where  e  is   the  error   term.      Substituting  equation    (4)    into    (3)    reveals 

E[(a0  *  alRe  +  e  +  W   '  E(a0  +  alRe  +  e  +  VE(V 
eo   =  2 

°M 


-4- 
(1  +  a1)[E(ReRM)  -  ECR^ECBjj)] 


o2 
m 

-  (1  +  a^Cgg)  (5) 

where 

al  "  (pa,eaa)/ae  • 

Equation  (5)  shows  that  if  the  correlation  between  the  component 
equilibrium  and  adjustment  returns  is  positive  (negative),  measured  beta 
will  be  greater  (smaller)  than  true  beta.  However,  the  direction  of  the 
discrepancy  between  equilibrium  and  measured  beta  does  not  necessarily 
depend  on  the  direction  of  the  adjustment  price  change.  If,  for  ex- 
ample, p    is  always  positive,  both  positive  and  negative  price  changes 
a,e 

will  result  an  increase  in  measured  beta. 

3.  A  Practical  Example 

In  a  recent  Bell  Journal  of  Economics  article  Pettway  [18]  examined 
whether  the  estimated  beta  of  a  36  electricity  utility  portfolio  was 
3table  enough  to  provide  good  estimates  of  subsequent  observed  3  values 
during  various  subperiods  in  the  1971-1976  period.   In  the  middle  of  the 
test  period  (April  18,  1974)  Consolidated  Edison  announced  it  was  omit- 
ting its  second  quarter  1974  dividend. 

Prior  to  the  skipped  dividend,  1971-1973,  the  utility  portfolio 
beta  was  relatively  low  (approximately  .40).  For  some  time  after  the 
dividend  omission,  1974-1975,  the  portfolio  beta  was  considerably  higher 
(approximately  .70),  and  then  it  settled  back  to  its  original  level  in 
the  last  three  quarters  of  1976.  Pettway  argues  that  the  skipped 


-5- 

dividend  may  have  changed  the  systematic  risk  of  electric  utilities  for 
the  period  immediately  following  the  dividend  episode. 

Pettway's  explanation  of  the  data  may  be  correct.  However,  this 
section  will  offer  an  interesting  alternative  interpretation  of  the  same 
data  based  upon  the  adjustment  phenomenon  described  in  equation  (5). 

Unfortunately,  a  direct  test  may  be  impossible.  The  correlation 

parameter  (p   )  in  the  model  cannot  be  directly  observed.  However,  it 
a,e 

is  possible  to  work  backward  and  infer  what  level  of  correlation  between 

R  and  R  would  create  the  6  effect  observed  by  Pettway.   The  reasonable- 
e      a 

ness  of  the  computed  magnitude  of  the  correlation  coefficient  will  pro- 
vide an  indirect  test  of  the  adjustment  beta  concept. 

A  review  of  Pettway's  findings  [18,  p.  244]  shows  that  the  beta  of 
his  36  electric  utility  portfolio  was  about  .41  before  the  April,  1974 
dividend  announcement.  The  portfolio  beta  averaged  above  .65  following 
the  dividend  announcement  before  returning  to  the  original  1971-1973 
level  of  .41  during  the  final  three  quarters  of  1976.   By  substituting 
these  values  into  equation  (5)  we  can  see  that 


3o=  <*  + «!><»«> 


.65  -  (1  +  a.) (.41) 

where 

P    a 

al  =  &'o     a  =  *59  •  (6) 

e 

Parts  of  the  Pettway  study  were  replicated  in  order  to  estimate  the 

variance  of  returns  before  and  after  the  April  1974  dividend  omission. 


-6- 

Thls  analysis  showed  the  standard  error  of  returns  increased  over  80% 
after  the  Consolidated  Edison  dividend  shock  and  settled  back  to  its  old 
value  when  the  portfolio  beta  itself  resumed  its  1971-1973  value  in  the 
final  three  quarters  of  1976.   Therefore, 


o     =  1.80a  ,  or  (7) 

o        e 

=  (a2  +  a2  +  2p  a  o   )1/2.  (8) 

e    a     e,a  e  a 

Substituting  (7)  into  (8)  yields 

(1.80c  )2  -  a2   +  a2   +  2p  a  a  (9) 

e      e    a     e,a  e  a 

o2   2p 

2  24  =  — -  +  — ^^ 
Z.Z4    2    0 

a  e 

e 

2 
Equations  (6)  and  (9)  can  be  solved  to  obtain  a  p    estimate  of  .178. 

e,a 

This  suggests  that  only  about  18%  of  the  variance  of  the  price  adjustment 
return  series  for  the  utility  portfolio  would  have  to  be  explained  by  the 

equilibrium  return  series  for  the  adjustment  phenomenon  of  equation  (5) 

2 
to  account  completely  for  Pettway's  findings. 

2 
We  feel  a  p    of  .18  is  reasonable.   It  suggests  that  the  relation- 
e,a 

ship  between  the  two  component  return  series  is  lower  than  the  relation- 
ship discovered  by  King  [11]  between  market  and  individual  security  re- 

2 
turns  (p  =  30%  to  60%),  but  higher  than  the  relationship  between  industry 

2 
and  security  returns  (p   »  io%) . 

Pettway's  analysis  illustrates  the  effect  on  a  portfolio  beta  from 

stock  price  adjustments  to  bad  news.  Studies  of  the  effects  of  stock 

splits  by  Fama,  Fisher,  Jensen  and  Roll  (1969) ,  and  Bar-Yosef  and  Brown 

(1977)  provide  examples  of  stock  price  adjustments  to  good  news. 


-7- 

FFJR  point  out  that  prior   to   a  stock  split  a  security  exhibits  a 
relatively  short   period  of  intense  upward  price  adjustments.      Bar-Yosef 
and  Brown  show  that   the  average  value  of  beta  increases   substantially 

during  this  upward  price  adjustment  period.  However,  as  in  the  Pettway 

3 
bad  news  analysis,  beta  later  returns  to  its  original  value.   This  time 

pattern  displayed  by  measured  beta  in  both  the  "good  news"  and  "bad 
news"  studies  is  consistent  with  the  adjustment  return  phenomenon  de- 
scribed in  equation  (5).   Specifically,  if  the  price  adjustment  is  not 
the  result  of  a  change  in  equilibrium  beta,  measured  beta  may  increase 
during  the  adjustment  period  but  it  will  eventually  return  to  its  orig- 
inal value. 

Conclusions  and  Implications 

Occasionally  a  security's  price  must  adjust  to  reflect  unanticipated 
new  information.  This  paper  points  out  that  the  adjustment  process  can 
create  measured  betas  having  little  relation  to  the  final,  post-adjust- 
ment, equilibrium  value.  A  model  of  a  "0  variability  phenomenon"  has 
been  offered  as  a  contributing  source  of  beta  non-stationarity  in  gen- 
eral, and  a  plausible  explanation  of  Pettway' s  and  Bar-Yosef  and  Brown's 
findings  in  particular. 

Ignorance  of  the  phenomenon  can  produce  serious  errors  when  uti- 
lizing ex  post  3  estimates  in  rate  regulatory  proceedings. 

(1)  After  substantial,  unanticipated  new  information  it  is  natural 
to  expect  a  new  value  for  systematic  risk.  A  researcher  who 
is  unaware  of  the  adjustment  phenomenon  might  assume  the  tem- 
porary adjustment  beta  Is  the  new  equilibrium  beta.   This  is 


-8- 

particularly  serious  (as  indicated  by  equations  1  through  5) 
because  the  adjustment  beta  does  not  necessarily  bear  any  re- 
lation to  the  final  equilibrium  value. 

(2)  A  researcher  might  blindly  compute  betas  using  historic  data 
which  includes  periods  of  adjustment  mixed  in  with  periods  of 
equilibrium.  This  approach  has  serious  heteroscedasticity 
problems  and  may  lead  to  serious  misestimation  of  beta.  The 
recommended  practice  [14,15]  of  estimating  a  specific  utility's 
beta  to  be  the  beta  measure  of  a  portfolio  of  comparable  firms 
does  not  necessarily  avoid  the  heteroscedasticity  problem 
posed  by  adjustment  periods.  Both  individual  firms  and  entire 
industries  can  experience  significant  adjustment  periods  as 
the  Pettway  and  Bar-Yosef  and  Brown  studies  reveal. 

(3)  The  researcher  might  drop  adjustment  periods  from  his  data 
base  and  ignore  them  entirely.  This  is  also  wrong.  Occasion- 
al violent  adjustments  in  security  prices  are  an  integral  part 
of  security  performance.  Moreover,  while  the  price  adjustment 
phenomenon  persists,  a  security's  adjustment  beta  has  the  same 
effect  on  portfolio  performance  as  betas  resulting  from  any 
other  cause.  Adjustment  betas  must  therefore  be  rewarded  by 
appropriate  (market  equilibrium)  levels  of  expected  return — 
just  like  any  other  betas. 

The  adjustment  phenomenon  is  probably  best  handled  by: 
(a)   Adjustment  and  equilibrium  betas  should  be  calculated 
separately  to  avoid  heteroscedasticity. 


-9- 

(b)  The  researcher  should  estimate  the  likelihood  that  an 
adjustment  beta  will  occur  during  the  period  for  which 
predictions  are  being  made.  He  must  also  assess  the 
probable  intensity  and  duration  of  such  an  adjustment. 
To  make  these  predictions,  the  researcher  should  look  at 
historic  data  over  an  extended  period  so  as  to  get  a  long 
term  feeling  for  the  incidence,  duration  and  intensity 
of  these  adjustment  periods. 

(c)  If  beta  is  to  be  used  to  determine  appropriate  rates  of 
return  for  utilities,  a  market  equilibrium  expected 
returns  should  be  calculated  for  equilibrium  and  adjust- 
ment betas.  These  different  expected  returns  should  be 
averaged  geometrically  with  weightings  determined  by  the 
probability  assessments  described  above.  This  will  pro- 
duce an  average  return  which  compensates  investors  for 
adjustment  and  equilibrium  systematic  risk. 


-10- 

FOOTNOTES 

Modern  portfolio  theory  is  more  than  the  CAPM,  and  the  usefulness 
of  beta  as  a  measure  of  security  risk  does  not  depend  on  the  strict  va- 
lidity of  the  CAPM  (Myers,  1978). 

Incomplete  lists  of  the  application  of  modern  portfolio  theory  in 
rate  regulatory  hearings  can  be  found  in  Myers  (1972b,  1978),  Carleton 
(1978),  Pettway  (1978),  and  Peseau  and  Zepp  (1978). 

2 
Believers  in  efficient  markets  will  have  trouble  accepting  the 

idea  of  a  non-instantaneous  adjustment  to  new  information.     Yet,    seme 

of  the  more  recent  studies  of  market  efficiency  allege  that  the  market 

is  very  slow  to  adjust  to  new  information.  For  example,  Latane  and 

Jones    (1979)    find  that  prices  don't  adjust   to  unanticipated   earnings 

for  5  to  6  months  after  the  end  of  the  quarter  and  3  months  after  the 

actual  announcement. 

If  this  is  the  adjustment  period  for  something  as  simple  as  a 

change  in  reported   earnings,   what  period  of  uncertainty   (and  adjustment) 

might  result  from  something  as  ambiguous  in  future  implication  as 

Consolidated  Edison's   skipped  dividend? 

3 
Unfortunately  neither  FFJR  or  Bar-Yosef  and  Brown  present  the 

change  in  variance  accompanying  the  change  in  beta  making  it  impossible 

for  us  to  calculate  the  implied  p    as  in  the  prior  example.  FFJR  do 

present  the  mean  absolute  deviation  and  it  seems  to  indicate  the  same 

general  level  of  increase  in  variability  as  the  Pettway  example. 

4 
Bar-Yosef  and  Brown  and  Pettway  dealt  with  the  heteroscedasticity 

problem  differently,  but  both  calculated  betas  which  proxy  to  some  ex- 
tent the  constructs  of  adjustment  and  equilibrium  betas.  Pettway  used 
the  occurrence  of  major  events  to  segment  his  study  period  into  sub- 
periods,  while  Bar-Yosef  and  Erown  used  a  moving  beta  measure. 

It  is  interesting  to  note  the  very  different  implications  of  past 
changes  in  beta  due  to  the  adjustment  phenomenon  and  past  changes  in 
beta  due  to  changes  in  equilibrium  beta.  A  researcher  has  no  reason  to 
expect  past  equilibrium  values  of  beta  to  reappear  and  only  the  most  re- 
cent equilibrium  betas  should  be  used  in  prediction.  The  researcher 
has  every  reason  to  believe  that  adjustment  periods  will  occur  in  the 
future.  Therefore,  such  data  must  be  used  in  prediction  of  beta. 

Ideally,  a  prediction  of  future  beta  should  include  a  pre-adjust- 
ment  equilibrium  beta  and  an  adjustment  beta  and  a  post  adjustment 
equilibrium  beta.  Unfortunately,  although  a  researcher  can  be  confident 
that  the  future  will  contain  periods  of  adjustment,  he  will  not  normally 
know  what  the  stock  is  adjusting  to. 

The  methodology  described  here  implicitly  assumes  the  pre  and  post 
adjustment  equilibrium  betas  are  equal.  If  the  price  adjustment  is  not 
in  response  to  a  change  in  equilibrium  beta  (as  seems  to  be  the  case  in 


-11- 


Pettway's  and  Bar-Yosef  and  Brown's  findings),  this  assumption  will  be 
correct.   If  equilibrium  beta  has  changed  the  assumption  will,  hopefully, 
be  reasonably  unbiased. 

The  justification  for  the  use  of  geometric  mean  is  best  illus- 
trated by  a  simple  example.  Assume  the  capital  market  equilibrium  ex- 
pected returns  for  adjustment  and  equilibrium  betas  are  ER  and  ER  re- 
spectively and  assume  the  security  is  predicted  to  spend  one  period  in 
adjustment  and  one  period  in  equilibrium.  The  capital  market  equilib- 
rium two  period  return  will  be 

ER„  =  (1  +  ER  ) (1  +  ER  )  -  1 
2         a       e 

the  mean  single  period  return  will  be 

ER  =  [(1  +  ER  )(1  +  ER  )  -  1]1/2  -  1 
n  a        e 

ER  will  then  compensate  investors  for  both  adjustment  and  equilibrium 
betas. 


-12- 


References 


1.  Bar-Yosef,  Sasson,  and  Brown,  L.D.  "A  Reexamination  of  Stock  Splits 
Using  Moving  Betas."  Journal  of  Finance,  Vol.  32,  No.  4  (September 
1977),  pp.  1069-1080. 

2.  Blume,  M.  E.  "On  the  Assessment  of  Risk."  Journal  of  Finance,  Vol. 
26  (March  1971),  pp.  1-10. 

3.  .   "Betas  and  Their  Regression  Tendencies."  Journal  of 

Finance,  Vol.  30  (June  1975),  pp.  785-795. 

4.  Breen,  W.  J.,  and  Lerner,  E.  M.   "On  The  Use  of  b  in  Regulatory 
Proceedings."  The  Bell  Journal  of  Economics  and  Management  Science, 
Vol.  3,  No.  2  (Autumn  1972),  pp.  612-621. 

5.  Brigham,  E.  F.,  and  Crum,  R.  L.  "On  the  Use  of  the  CAPM  in  Public 
Utility  Rate  Cases."  Financial  Management,  Vol.  VI,  No.  2  (Summer 
1977),  pp.  7-15. 

6.  .   "Reply  to  Comments  on  'Use  of  the  CAPM  in  Public 

Utility  Rate  Cases'."  Financial  Management,  Vol.  VII,  No.  3 
(Autumn  1978),  pp.  72-76. 

7.  Carleton,  W.  T.  "A  Highly  Personal  Comment  On  the  Use  of  the  CAPM 
In  Public  Utility  Rate  Cases."  Financial  Management,  Vol.  VII, 
No.  3  (Autumn  1978),  pp.  57-59.  " 

8.  Fama,  E.  F.,  Fisher,  L.,  Jensen,  M.  C,  and  Roll,  R.   "The 
Adjustment  of  Stock  Prices  To  New  Information."  International 
Economic  Review,  Vol.  10,  No.  1  (February,  1969),  pp.  1-21. 

9.  Francis,  Jack  Clark  "Statistical  Analysis  of  Risk  Surrogates  for 
NYSE  Stocks."  Journal  of  Financial  and  Quantitative  Analyses, 
December  1979,  pp.  981-997. 

10.  Gilster,  J.  E.,  and  Linke,  C.  M.  "More  on  the  Estimation  of  Beta 
for  Public  Utilities:  Biases  Resulting  From  Structural  Shifts  in 
True  Beta."  Financial  Management,  Vol.  VII,  No.  3  (Autumn  1978), 
pp.  60-65. 

11.  King,  B.  J.  "Market  and  Industry  Factors  In  Stock  Price  Behavior." 
Journal  of  Business,  January  1966,  pp.  139-190. 

12.  Latane,  H.  A.,  and  Jones,  C.  P.   "Standardized  Unexpected  Earnings — 
1971-1977."  Journal  of  Finance,  June  1979,  pp.  717-724. 

13.  Levy,  R.  A.   "Stationarity  of  Beta  Coefficients."  Financial 
Analysts  Journal,  Vol.  27  (November-December  1971),  pp.  55-62. 


-13- 


14.  Myers,  S.  C.   "The  Application  of  Finance  Theory  to  Public  Utility 
Rate  Cases."  The  Bell  Journal  of  Economics  and  Management  Science, 
Vol.  3,  No.  1  (Spring  1972a),  pp.  58-97. 

15.  .   "On  the  Use  of  b  in  Regulatory  Proceedings:  A 

Comment."  The  Bell  Journal  of  Economics  and  Management  Science, 
Vol.  3,  No.  2  (Autumn  1972b),  pp.  622-627. 

16.  .   "On  the  Use  of  Modern  Portfolio  Theory  In  Public 

Utility  Rate  Cases:   Comment."  Financial  Management,  Vol.  VII, 
No.  3  (Autumn  1978),  pp.  66-68.  " 

17.  Peseau,  D.  E.,  and  Zepp,  T.  M.   "On  the  Use  of  the  CAPM  in  Public 
Utility  Rate  Cases:   Comment."  Financial  Management,  Vol.  VII, 
No.  3  (Autumn  1973),  pp.  52-56. 

18.  Pettway,  R.  H.  "On  the  Use  of  b  in  Regulatory  Proceedings:  An 
Empirical  Examination."  The  Bell  Journal  of  Economics,  Vol.  9, 
No.  1  (Spring  1978),  pp.  239-248. 

19.  Porter,  R.  B.,  and  Ezzell,  J.  R.   "A  Note  On  the  Predictive  Ability 
of  Beta  Coefficients."  Journal  of  Business  Research,  Vol.  3 
(October  1975),  pp.  365-372. 

20.  Rosenburg,  B.,  and  Guy,  J.  "Prediction  of  Beta  From  Investment 
Fundamentals:  Part  One."  Financial  Analysts  Journal,  May-June 
1976,  pp.  60-72. 

21.  .   "Prediction  of  Beta  From  Investment  Fundamentals: 

Part  Two."  Financial  Analysts  Journal,  July-August  1976,  pp.  62-70. 

22.  Sharpe,  W.  F.   "On  the  Use  of  the  CAPM  in  Public  Utility  Rate  Cases: 
Comment."  Financial  Management,  Vol.  VII,  No.  3  (Autumn  1978), 

p.  71. 


M/E/192 


^^OONOs^