Skip to main content

Full text of "The nonstationarity of systematic risk for bonds"

See other formats


OlMlVtRSlTY  Of 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

AT  URBANA-CHAMPAiCaS 

STACKS 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/nonstationarityo497jaha 


Faculty  Working  Papers 


College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 

Univorslty  of  lllinoit  at  U  r  b  a  n  a  •  C  ha  m  pa  i  g  n 


FACULTY  UORKIWG  PAPERS 

College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 

University  of  Illinois  at  Urb ana- Champaign 

July  20,  1978 


THE  NONSTATIONAPvITY  OF  SYSTEIIATIC  RISK  FOR  BONDS 


Ali  Jahankhani,  A'^';istant  Professor 
George  E.  Pinches,  University  of  Kansas 


/M97 


Summary; 

Recently  a  number  of  researchers  have  attempted  to  employ  the 
market  model  to  estimate  systematic  risk  (i.e.,  beta)  for  bonds.   In 
this  study  we  reviewed  theoretical  evidence  which  suggests  bond 
betas  can  be  expected  to  be  nonstatlonary.  This  nonstationarity  is 
a  function  of  the  duration  of  a  bond,  the  standard  deviation  of  the 
change  in  the  yield  to  maturity  of  a  bond  relative  to  the  standard 
deviation  of  the  return  on  the  market  portfolio,  and  the  correlation 
betv7een  the  change  in  the  yield  to  maturity  of  a  bond  and  the  return 
on  the  market  portfolio.  Hotjever,  all  bonds  will  not  necessarily 
have  nonstatlonary  betas  in  a  given  time  period  since  it  is  possible 
that  these  factors  may  occasionally  counteract  one  another. 

Empirical  tests  indicated  that  over  80  percent  of  the  bonds  ejc» 
amined  had  nonstatlonary  betas.  The  primary  factor  differentiating 
bonds  with  nonstatlonary  betas  from  those  with  stationary  betas  was 
the  substantially  higher  relative  standard  deviation  in  the  change  in 
the  yield  to  maturity  for  bonds  with  nonstatlonary  betas.  The  larger 
standard  deviation  was  caused  by  the  higher  average  coupon  rates  and 
yields  to  maturity  for  bonds  \rLth   nonstatlonary  betas.  The  theoretical 
and  empirical  results  of  this  study  indicate  bond  betas,  in  general, 
tend  to  be  nonstatlonary.  Hence,  further  use  of  them  appears  to  be 
of  very  questionable  value. 


THE  NONSTATIONARITY  OF  SYSTEMATIC  RISK  FOR  BONDS 

I,   INTRODUCTION 
In  the  last  decade  Increasing  use  has  been  made  of  the  Capital  Asset 
PrlclTig  Model  (CAFM)  developed  by  Sharpe  [31],  Llntner  [7]  and  extended 
by  Bl£.ck  [2].  In  this  model  the  only  relevant  risk  of  an  asset  Is  the 
systematic  risk  which  Is  measured  by  the  covarlance  of  the  ex-ante  return 
on  th(t  asset  with  the  ex-ante  return  on  the  market  portfolio.  Since  the 
ex-anl.e  returns  cannot  be  observed,  researchers  have  used  historical  data 
to  estimate  the  systematic  risk.  The  market  model,  which  has  been  the 
most  common  method  of  estimating  the  relative  systematic  risk  (3.)  states 
that: 

R.^  -  a.  +  e.R  ^  +  e.^,  (1) 

it    1    1  mt    it' 

where  R. .  and  R   are  returns  on  1   asset  and  the  market  portfolio 

2 
respeiitively,  and  B.  is  computed  as  cov(R.  ,R  )/o  (R  ).  The  use  of 

historical  data  to  estimate  B.  is  justified  only  if  the  Joint  distribu- 
tion of  returns  on  the  asset  and  the  market  portfolio  is  stable  over  time. 
Under  these  conditions  3.  will  be  stationary  and  hence  the  market  model 
will  ]>e  an  appropriate  method  of  estimating  fi.. 

]lecently  a  number  of  researchers  have  applied  the  market  model  to 
estlxuite  systematic  risk  for  bonds.  Percival  [27]  estimated  bond  betas 
and  tlien  attempted  to  explain  them  as  a  function  of  the  bond  character- 
istic)}. Friend  and  Blume  [14]  and  McCallum  [21]  also  estimated  bond 
systematic  risk  while  Rellly  and  Joehnk  [28]  examined  the  relationship 
betwe>3n  bond  betas  and  bond  ratings.  Finally,  Warner  [34]  estimated 


3  '-■ 


C       ■....  J<i;j;!"'! 


-2- 

bond  betas  and  then  examined  the  risk  adjusted  performance  of  bonds  for 
firms  in  bankruptcy  versus  the  performance  of  bonds  for  similar  firms 
not  in  bankruptcy. 

The  Increasing  use  of  the  bond  betas  appears  to  be  without  support 
since  there  are  theoretical  considerations  suggesting  bond  betas  are 
inherently  nonstationary.   In  the  presence  of  this  nonstatlonarlty ,  bond 
betas  appear  to  be  poor  estimates  of  systematic  (or  any  other  kind  of) 
risk  for  bonds.  The  purposes  of  this  stxidy  are  threefold:   1)  to  examine 
the  theoretical  considerations  indicating  nonstatlonarlty  of  bond  betas; 
2)  to  test  empirically  whether  the  betas  of  individual  bonds  are  stationary 
over  the  1969-1975  time  period;  and  3)  to  explain  the  observed  stationarlty/ 
nonstationarity  in  terms  of  the  factors  that  cause  the  nonstatlonarlty 
In  bond  beta.   In  Section  II  theoretical  arguments  for  the  nonstatlonarlty 
of  bond  betas  are  reviewed,  while  Section  III  contains  the  methodology  em- 
ployed. The  empirical  results  are  presented  and  discussed  in  Section  IV 
and  the  conclusions  are  contained  in  Section  V. 

II.   THEOEIETICAL  CONSIDERATIONS 
Several  recent  studies  [4,15,18,35]  have  examined  a  specific 
time-risk  relationship  using  a  measure  of  time  known  as  duration.  The 
concept  of  duration  was  first  introduced  by  Macaulay  [19]  in  his  study 
of  bond  yields.  Unlike  the  time  to  maturity,  which  looks  only  at  the 
last  payment,  duration  gives  some  weight  to  the  time  at  which  each  cash 
payment  is  received.  The  weight  assigned  to  each  period  is  the  present 
value  of  the  cash  payment  for  that  period  divided  by  the  current  market 
price  of  the  security.  For  a  bond,  duration  at  time  t^  is  computed  as: 


-3- 

N  N 

D^  -  [  Z   (t.-tf.)  A  1  /  2  A  (2) 

where  A   Is  the  present  value  measured  at  time  t^  of  cash  flows  to  be 

3 
received  at  time  t.  and  N  is  the  number  of  years  to  maturity.  From  (2) 

it  is  apparent  that  duration  is  a  function  of  the  time  to  maturity,  the 
size  of  interim  coupon  payments,  the  yield  to  maturity  and  the  size  of  the 
principal  payment.  For  a  zero-coupon  bond,  duration  is  identical  to  the 
time  to  maturity.  The  litik  between  the  bond  price  volatility  and  dura- 
tion was  developed  by  Fisher  [13]  and  extended  by  Hopewell  and  Kaufman  [15] . 
Assuming  continous  compounding,  the  percentage  change  in  a  bond  price  is 
related  to  duration  by: 
dP, 


^'  -  -D,,  dy,,,  (3> 


^it    ^'  '^^ 

where  dP.  and  P.  are  the  price  change  and  initial  price  of  bond  i  at 
time  t  respectively.  D.  is  the  duration  of  the  bond  at  time  t  and  dy. 
is  the  change  in  the  yield  to  maturity.  Equation  (3)  shows  that  duration 
is  a  constant  of  proportionality  relating  percentage  changes  in  boiui  prices 
to  changes  in  the  yield  i^Vj^^  • 

Boquist,  Racette  and  Schlarbaum  [4]  developed  a  theoretical  model 
which  links  the  beta  of  a  default  free  bond  to  duration: 

cov(dy  ,R  )  o(dy  ) 

^it  -  '\t     i'"  ;   °  -^it  ^^'Ht>\t^  Torr '  <^> 

a   (R^j.)  mt 

where  a(dy.  )  is  the  standard  deviation  of  dy^  ,  o(R^^)  is  the  standard 
deviation  of  the  return  on  the  market  portfolio,  and  P(*iy4t»^mt^  ^®  *^^® 
correlation  coefficient  between  changes  in  the  yield  to  maturity  and  the 
return  on  the  market  portfolio.   (As  argued  by  Boquist  et  al.,  the  corre- 
lation coefficient  is  expected  to  be  negative  for  most  bonds.)  From 


-4- 


eqiiation  (4)  it  is  apparent  that  &.  is  dependent  upon  the  duration  of 
the  bond,  the  correlation  coefficient  between  changes  in  the  yield  to 
maturity  of  the  bond  and  the  return  on  the  market,  and  the  standard  devia- 
tion of  the  changes  in  the  yield  to  maturity  for  the  bond  relative  to  the 
standard  deviation  of  the  return  on  the  market  portfolio.   Therefore, 
depending  upon  the  interaction  of  changes  over  time  in  the  following  three 

factors:  1)  U^^;  2)  -P(^yit'\t^'  ^^   ^^  °^^^±t^^°^\t^  ^^^  ^°^  ^^^^ 
may  be  stationary  or  nonstantionary.  As  a  bond  progresses  toward 
maturity  the  duration,  D.  ,  will  shorten  which,  ceteris  paribus,  should 
cause  3.  to  decrease.  The  second  factor,  -p(dy.  ,R  ),  may  also  cause 
p.  to  decrease  over  time.  Through  the  passage  of  time  the  maturity  of 
a  bond  becomes  shorter.  In  general  short-term  yields  tend  to  be  less  cor- 
related with  the  return  on  the  market  portfolio  than  the  long-term  yields. 

2 
Therefore  as  time  passes  the  second  factor  will  cause  ^.     to  decrease. 

Finally,  the  third  factor,  o(dy,  )/o(R  ),  should  cause  p.  to  increase 
because,  as  Malkiel  [20]  has  shown,  short-term  yields  tend  to  be  more 
volatile  than  long-term  yields.  Unless  these  factors  exactly  offset  each 
other  bond  betas  estimated  from  historical  time  series  data  will  be  non- 
stationary. 

III.  METHODOLOGY 
A.   SAMPLE 

In  order  to  empirically  test  for  the  nonstationarity  of  bond 
systematic  risk  a  homogeneous  group  of  bonds  was  required.  The  selection 
criteria  employed  resulted  in  bonds  being  selected  if  they  were  public 
utility  or  industrial  bonds  continuously  rated  (without  any  change)  in 
the  top  four  bond  rating  categories  by  both  Moody's  and  Standard  &  Poor's 


-5- 


between  May  31,  1969  and  May  31,  1975,  were  issued  between  January  1, 

1966  and  March  1,  1969,  had  an  original  maturity  of  at  le^tst  20  years 

3 

and  an  original  issue  size  of  at  least  !?10  million.   In  jiddition,  the 

bonds  could  not  be  subordinated  or  convertible,  nor  could  they  be  Issued 

4 
with  warrants  attached.   In  cases  where  there  were  more  than  one  bond 

per  company  that  met  the  selection  criteria,  the  most  rectsnt  issue  was 

selected.  Application  of  these  criteria  resulted  in  84  bonds  being 

selected  of  which  42  were  public  utility  bonds  and  42  were  industrial 

bonds. 


B.  VARIABLES 

1.  Holding  Period  Return 

Monthly  holding  period  returns  for  bonds  were  comput(id  as: 

-  I  +  AP^ 

where  I  is  the  periodic  interest  payment  per  $100  of  par  value; 
m  is  the  number  of  holding  periods  between  interest  payments  (for  most 
bonds  m  =  6  months) ;  n  is  the  number  of  periods  accrued  toward  the  next 
interest  payment  at  the  end  of  period  t;  and  P  -  is  the  laarket  price 
of  the  bond  at  the  end  of  period  t-1. 

Some  authors  have  used  different  methods  to  measure  the  riiturn  on  bonds* 
Yawitz  and  Marshall  [36]  used  purchase  yield  as  a  measure  of  return  on 
U.S.  Government  bonds.  They  reasoned  that  it  is  a  better  measure  of  the 
expected  return  because  over  the  life  of  the  bond,  price  i:hanges  must 
stim  to  zero.  This  argiunent  is  valid  only  if  the  investorii'  holding  period 
is  equal  to  the  life  of  the  bond.  Yield  to  maturity  has  also  been  used 
as  a  measure  of  the  returns  on  bonds  by  Duvall  and  Cheney  [10] .  They 


Ir 


;3i',    S;.: 


-6- 

argued  that  yield  to  maturity  is  a  more  reliable  estimate  of  the  expected 
return  than  the  ex-post  measure  as  formulated  in  equation  (5).   Reilly  and 
Joehnk  [28]  employed  the  percentage  change  in  the  yield  to  maturity  as  a 
measure  of  the  bond  return.  Again  these  authors  are  implicitly  assuming 
that  investors  have  a  holding  period  equal  to  the  life  of  the  bond,  the 
bond  Is  default  free,  and  investors  can  reinvest  the  intermediate  interest 
payments  at  a  rate  equal  to  the  yield  to  maturity.  Because  of  the  above 
mentioned  problems  with  these  return  measures,  we  prefer  to  use  equation 
(5)  to  measure  the  holding  period  return. 

2.  Market  Portfolio 

Traditionally  a  portfolio  of  common  stocks  has  been  employed  as  a 
proxy  for  the  market  portfolio.  According  to  the  CAPM,  the  market  portfolio 
should  contain  all  risky  assets  such  as  common  stocks,  bonds,  preferred 
stocks,  real  estate,  human  capital,  etc.   Construction  of  such  a  portfolio 
is  very  difficult,  if  not  impossible,  because  the  data  on  thesa  assets  are 
not  readily  available. 

A  review  of  the  literature  on  bonds  reveals  that  different  proxies 
for  the  market  portfolio  have  been  employed.   Percival  [27]  and  McCalium 
[21]  used  an  equally  weighted  portfolio  of  their  bonds.  Friend  and  Blume 
[14]  and  Warner  [34]  utilized  a  common  stock  portfolio,  while  Reilly  and 
Joehnk  [28]  used  three  different  bond  portfolios  and  two  different  common 
stock  portfolios.   As  demonstrated  by  Roll  [29]  the  choice  of  the  market 
portfolio  greatly  affects  the  estimated  beta.   In  this  study  a  value 
weighted  market  portfolio  is  constructed  which  includes  common  stocks, 
corporate  bonds  and  government  bonds  each  weighted  by  their  corresponding 


-7- 

market  value.   We  believe  this  is  a  more  reasonable  proxy  for  the 
market  portfolio  and  clearly  superior  to  the  proxies  employed  in  other 
studies. 

C.   STATISTICAL  TECHNIQUES 

Since  the  stationarity  of  beta  is  a  time  related  phenomenon,  the 
traditional  method  of  testing  for  stationarity  using  correlation  coeffi- 
cients is  inappropriate.  There  are  basically  two  problems  with  the  use 
of  the  correlation  coefficient  as  a  measure  of  stationarity.  First, 
when  using  equation  (1)  to  estimate  3,  it  is  implicitly  assumed  that  g 
is  stationary  during  the  estimation  period.  Second,  the  correlation 
coefficient  cannot  be  used  to  determine  the  stationary  of  the  individual 
securities.  It  is,  in  essence,  an  aggregate  measure  of  stationarity  of 
the  betas  for  a  group  of  aecurities  or  portfolios.  An  ideal  test  for 
stationarity  should  detect  the  constancy  of  the  security  beta  over  time 
by  examining  whether  or  not  the  regression  coefficients  in  the  market 
model  vary  over  time. 

Since  we  were  primarily  interested  in  the  stability  of  S.  (not 
o,  and  e.  simultaneously)  we  also  estimated  g.  by; 

^it  ==  ^iV  ^  ^it*  ^^> 

where  r^^  =  R^^  -  R^^,  r^^  -  R^^  -  R^^,  R^^  is  the  risk  free  rate  of 

7 
interest  and  the  intercept  (a.)  was  supressed.   To  correctly  examine 

the  behavior  g,  over  time,  equation  (6)  is  rewritten  as; 

y,  =  e,  x^  +  e,  (7) 


-8- 


where  subscript  t  on  3  indicates  that  it  may  vary  over  time,  y  is 
the  vector  of  returns  on  a  bond,  x  is  the  vector  of  returns  on  the 
market  portfolio,  and  e  is  the  vector  of  disturbances.  The  null 
h3rpo thesis  for  stationarity  is  formulated  as: 

Hq!   Bj^  =  32  "  •••  =  ^T*  ^^^ 

In  words,  the  null  hypothesis  states  that  3  is  stable  over  time.  The 
alternate  hypothesis  is  that  not  all  3's  for  an  individual  bond  are 
equal . 

The  stationarity  of  3  problem  is  a  special  case  of  the  general  class 
of  problems  concerned  with  detection  of  changes  in  the  regression  model 
structures  over  time.  Early  work  on  detecting  changes  in  a  model  struc- 
ture employed  the  ordinary  least  square  (OLS)  residuals  or  the  cumulative 
sum  of  the  OLS  residuals.  The  difficulty  with  these  approaches,  however, 
is  that  there  is  no  known  method  of  assessing  the  significance  of  the 
nonstationarity  in  the  regression  coefficients  (cf.,  Mehr  and  McFadden 
[22]).  To  avoid  problems  associated  with  the  OLS  residuals.  Brown  and 
Durbin  [6],  and  Brown,  Durbin,  and  Evans  (BDE)  [7]  proposed  using  recur- 
sive residuals.  BDE  have  shown  that  under  the  null  hypothesis  of  station- 
arity the  recursive  residuals  have  the  desirable  properties  of  being 
uncorrelated,  with  zero  mean  and  constant  variance,  and  therefore  are 
Independent  of  each  other  under  the  normality  assumption.  Recursive 
residiials  are  also  preferrable  to  OLS  residuals  for  detecting  nonstation- 
arity in  3  because  until  a  change  takes  place  the  recursive  residuals 
behave  exactly  as  specified  in  the  null  hypothesis.  Recursive  residuals 
are  defined  as: 


-9- 

w  «  (y  -x'b  -)/[!  +  x'  (X'  ,x  j"-^x  3*^  (9) 

r   ^-^r  r  r-1'  ■■     r    r-1  r-1    r 

r  =  kt-l,  ...,  T 

where  k  Is  the  number  of  regression  coefficients  (1  in  equation  (7)), 
^r-1  "   [x^.---.\_iK  \   =  (x;x^)~^x;y^,  and  Y^  =  (y^ y^ . 

For  each  value  of  r,  which  in  our  study  takes  a  value  between  2  and  72, 

g 
the  recursive  residual  was  computed  using  equation  (9) . 

BDE  derived  a  statistical  test  for  stationarity  using  the  cumu- 
lative sum  of  the  squared  recursive  residuals.  This  test,  the  cusum 
of  squares  test,  detects  both  systematic  and  random  changes  in  the  3 
and  is  based  on  the  following  formulation: 

r        T 

s  =  (  Z   w^)/(  Z   w^),  r=k+l T.  (10) 

^   j=lH-l  ^  j-'lcfl  ^ 

Under  the  null  hypothesis  s  has  a  beta  distribution  with  mean 

(r-k)/(T-k).  BDE  suggested  constructing  a  confidence  internal  for  s  as 

[(r-k)/(T-k)]  +  C  where  C  is  chosen  from  Table  1  of  Durbin  [9].  The 

stationarity  hypothesis  will  be  rejected  if  |s  -((r-k)/(T-k)) |>C  for 

any  r  Included  in  [fc4-l,T]. 

If  6  is  expected  to  change  systematically  over  time  another  test 

can  be  used  to  detect  such  changes  [7].  This  type  of  nonstationarity  can 

be  tested  using  an  F-test.  Under  the  null  hypothesis  of  stationarity, 

equation  (7)  can  be  rewritten  as: 

where  3^  denotes  that  the  beta  coefficient  is  stationary.  Equation  (11) 
is  the  reduced  model;  under  the  alternate  hypothesis  3  is  assumed  to 
change  linearly  with  time,  or 


-10- 


y,  -  x;  3^  +  e^.  ^     (12) 

where     ^t  "  ^0  "*"  ^'^*   ^°^  ^^'^^ 

where  6  Is  the  coefficient  of  time.  Substitution  of  equation  (13)  into  (12) 
yields: 

^t  '  ""t^^O  "^  ^'^^   "^  ^t»  ^^'^^ 

which  is  the  full  model.  The  null  hypothesis  of  stationarity  is  tested 
by  a  comparison  of  the  mean-square  increase  in  the  explained  variation 
with  the  error  variance.  This  F-test  is: 

SSE(R)-SSE(F)  .  SSE(F) 
^  '     df(R)-df (F)   ^  df (F)  (15) 

where  SSE(R)  and  SSE(F)  are  the  error  sum  of  squares  of  the  reduced  and 
full  models,  respectively.  Likewise,  df(R)  and  df (F)  are  the  degrees  of 
freedom  associated  with  the  SSE(R)  and  SSE(F).   It  should  be  noted  that 
this  F-test  detects  only  systematic  changes  in  g,  whereas  the  cusum  of 
squares  test  detects  both  systematic  and  random  changes  in  3.  In  this 
study  the  nonstationarity  detected  by  the  F-test  is  called  "systematic 
nonstationarity",  while  the  nonstationarity  detected  by  the  cusum  of  squares 
test  but  not  with  the  F-test  is  called  "random  nonstationarity". 

IV.   EMPIRICAL  RESULTS 
A.  SAMPLE  CHARACTERISTICS 

In  Table  1  the  sample  characteristics  are  reported  broken  down  by 
industrial  versus  public  utility  bonds.  In  general,  the  coupon  rates 
are  lower  for  the  industrial  bonds  as  are  the  years  to  maturity  while 


-11- 

TABLE  1 
Characteristics  of  the  Sampled  Bonds 


TOTAL 


INDUSTRIAL 


Number 


84 


42 


PUBLIC  UTILITY  42 


Coupon 
Rate 

6.452  . 


Issue   Years  to 
Size   Maturity   3^ 


60.071 


27.274 


.410   .181   .423 


(.638)   (48.646)   (3.671)  (.187)  (.126)  (.178) 


6,129  81.905 

(.564)  (65.490) 

6.775  38.238 

(.541)  (41.194) 


25.714    .412   .177   .428 

(2.361)  (.245)  (.154)  (.232) 

28.833    .407   .185   .419 

(4.090)  (.104)  (.092)  (.102) 


Standard  deviation  in  parethesis. 

In  millions  of  dollars. 
'^From  the  market  model  given  by  equation  (1) . 
^rom  the  market  model  given  by  equation  (6). 


-12- 

the  Issue  sizes  are  larger  for  the  Industrial  bonds  than  for  public 
utility  bonds.  These  findings  are  consistent  with  the  typical  charac- 
teristics of  public  utility  bonds  which  have  higher  coupon  rates  and 

longet  maturities.  The  average  3  of  84  bonds  obtained  from  equation 

2 
(1)  is  0.410  with  an  average  R  of  0.181.  The  average  3  of  the  bonds 

obtained  by  employing  equation  (6)  is  .423  (where  a,  was  suppressed) 

which  is  virtually  the  same  as  that  obtained  by  using  eqxiation  (1) . 

There  are  no  significant  differences  in  bond  betas  between  the  public 

9 
utility  and  industrial  groups.   In  the  rest  of  the  study  $.  as 

estimated  by  equation  (6)  is  employed. 

B.   STATIONARITY  OF  SYSTEMATIC  RISK  FOR  BONDS 

The  cusum  of  squares  test  (for  random  nonstationarity)  and  the  F-test 
(for  systematic  nonstationarity)  were  applied  to  each  bond  to  detenoine 
whether  the  individual  bond  betas  were  stable  or  not  over  the  period 
examined.  The  results  of  these  tests  (employing  a  5  percent  significance 
level)  are  reported  in  Table  2.  Examination  of  this  table  indicates 
that  69.05  percent  [(24+5)/42]  of  the  industrial  bonds  had  nonstationary 
betas,  while  95.24  percent  [ (24+16) /42]  of  the  public  utility  bonds  had 
nonstationary  bond  betas.  Overall,  82.14  percent  [ (48+21) /84]  of  the 
bonds  examined  had  nonstationary  betas  with  25  percent  (21/84)  of  the 
bonds  exhibiting  systematic  nonstationarity  and  57.14  percent  (48/84) 
indicating  random  nonstationarity.  Not  only  were  more  of  the  public 
utility  bond  betas  unstable,  but  they  also  exhibited  more  systematic 
nonstationarity  than  did  the  Industrial  bonds.  These  results,  for  a     ^ 
very  homogeneous  set  of  bonds,  provide  strong  empirical  support  for  the 


rO*-;Kv  .«.;.^!  J::  = 


(l9V»l 


•>i'..  '      0 


io;.  i.^>, 


-13- 


TABLE  2 


Niimber  of  Bonds  With  Nonstatlonary  Beta 
Based  on  the  Cusum  of  Squares  and  F  Tests 
(5  percent  significance  level) 


INDUSTRIAL 

13 

PUBLIC  UTILITY 

2 

TOTAL 

15 

Nonstatlonary 
Stationary Random Systematic Total 

24  5  42 

24  16  42 

48  21  84 


-14- 

theoretlcal  considerations  presented  in  section  II  indicating  that  bond 
betas  are  inherently  nonstationary. 

Since  our  concern  is  not  with  the  nature  of  the  nonstationarity, 
per  se,  the  rest  of  the  analysis  will  focus  on  two  groups  of  bonds — those 
with  stationary  betas  and  those  with  nonstationary  betas  (encompassing 
both  random  and  systematic  nonstationarity) .   In  Table  3  the  salient  char- 
acteristics of  these  two  groups  of  bonds  are  presented.  As  expected 
(based  on  Table  1  and  the  knowledge  that  more  public  utility  bonds  are 
Included  in  the  nonstationary  group),  the  nonstationary  bonds  had  a 
significantly  higher  average  coupon  rate,  significantly  smaller  average 
size  and  significantly  lower  betas  than  bonds  with  stationary  betas. 
While  not  statistically  significant  (at  the  5  percent  level),  the  bonds 
with  nonstationary  betas  tend  to  have  slightly  lower  bond  ratings,  while 
there  is  virtually  no  difference  in  the  average  years  to  maturity.  The 
higher  average  coupon  rate  for  bonds  with  nonstationary  betas  can  also 
be  seen  by  examining  Table  4.  Almost  50  percent  (34/69)  of  the  bonds 
with  nonstationary  betas  have  coupon  rates  greater  than  6.5  percent  while 
only  13  percent  (2/15)  of  the  bonds  with  stationary  betas  have  coupon 
rates  greater  than  6.5  percent. 

As  presented  in  Section  II,  theoretical  considerations  indicate 
bond  betas  should  be  inherently  unstable  and  this  instability  is  related 
to:  1)  the  duration  of  the  bond,  D,  ;  2)  the  correlation  between  the 
change  in  the  yield  to  maturity  of  the  bond  and  the  return  on  the  market, 
-p(dy.  ,R  );  and  3)  the  standard  deviation  of  the  change  in  the  yield   ^ 
to  maturity  of  the  bond  relative  to  the  standard  deviation  of  the  return 
on  the  market,  a(dy.  )/a(R  ).   (As  indicated  in  equation  (4)  the 


X'j 


'*yi^. 


-15- 


TABLE  3 


Statistics  on  Bonds  with  Stationary 
and  Nonstationary  Bond  Betas 


Number 

Stationary 
15 

Nonstationary 
69 

F  Ratio 

Probability 

Coupon  Rate 

6.005 
(.577)^ 

6.550 
(.612) 

9.93^ 

.0023 

Years  to  Maturity'^ 

19.267 
(4.399) 

20.043 
(3.771) 

.91 

.3439 

Issue  Size 

110.000 
(73.969) 

49.217 
(49.001) 

16.61 

.0001 

Bond  Rating® 

2.333 
(.900) 

2.696 
(.845) 

2.21 

.1407 

Bond  Beta 

.535 
(.166) 

.399 
(.173) 

7.83 

.0064 

Standard  deviation  in  parenthesis. 
With  1  and  82  degrees  of  freedom. 
'As  of  January  1,  1975. 


In  millions  of  dollars. 


'1  =  Aaa/AAA,  2  =  Aa/AA,  3  =  A/A  and  4  =  Baa/BBB. 


-16- 


TABLE  4 


Coupon  Rates  for  Bonds  with 
Stationary  and  Nonstationary  Bond  Betas 


COUPON  RATE 

<  5.5 

5.51 
to  6.00 

6.01 
to  6.5 

6.51 
to  7.00 

7.01 
to  7.50 

>  7.50 

TOTAL 

Stationary 
Nonstationary 

3 

4 

6 

14 

4 
17 

1 
16 

1 
17 

1 

15 
69 

-17- 


relatlonship  between  3.  and  these  factors  carries  a  negative  sign — for 
convenience  we  have  appended  the  negative  sign  to  the  correlation.)  In 
order  to  examine  the  relative  Impact  of  these  factors  on  the  observed 
stability/instability  of  the  bond  betas,  we  arbitrarily  divided  the  study 
period  into  three  24  month  periods.  Then  we  calculated  the  average  dura- 
tion, Djj.*   the  average  correlation,  p(dy.  ,R  )  and  the  average 
standard  deviation,  a(dy.  )  for  the  first  and  last  24  month  periods 
and  the  relative  change  in  these  variables  from  the  first  to  the  last 
period.   (Since  the  standard  deviation  of  the  market,  a(R  )  is  the  same 
for  all  bonds,  we  ignore  it  and  focus  solely  on  o(dy.  ), 

The  results  of  this  analysis  of  the  change  in  duration,  correlation 
and  standard  deviation  for  the  two  groups  of  bonds  are  presented  in  Table 
5.  For  the  bonds  with  stationary  betas,  the  duration  decreased,  the 
standard  deviation  in  the  yield  to  maturity  increased,  and  the  correla- 
tion between  the  change  in  the  yield  to  maturity  and  the  return  on  the 
market  portfolio  decreased  from  the  first  to  the  third  24  month  period. 
The  same  directional  changes  occurred  for  the  bonds  with  nonstationary 
betas.  However,  the  Important  difference  in  the  two  groups  of  bonds  is 
the  relative  change  (columns  (3)  and  (6)  of  Table  5)  in  these  three 
variables  for  the  two  bond  groups. 

Starting  with  duration.  Table  5  indicates  that  the  relative  change 
in  duration  between  bonds  with  stationary  or  nonstationary  betas  are 
approximately  the  same.  Hence,  differences  in  average  duration  are  not 
significant  In  dlfferrentiating  between  bonds  with  stationary  versus 
nonstationary  betas  (given  the  relatively  homogeneous  maturity  of  the 
bonds  under  study) . 


cr 

p 

£^ 

o 

H. 

» 

rt 

t-' 

sr 

n 

e 

H 

j-i 

o> 

& 

rt 

0 

(t> 

PL. 

p. 

00 

i-ti 

ro 

H 

P- 

^ 

« 

<M 

H» 

H 

H- 

(0 

OQ 

<t) 

C 

CO 

H 

<t) 

o 

03 

M> 

« 

Ml 

H- 

M 

rt 

<0 

B* 

(S 

O. 

s 

Q 

o 

B 

H 

m 

(a 

a. 

(C 

o 

to 


D 


Ui 


■D 

Q 

/-N 

^•-N 

o. 

Cl 

VcJ 

^ 

H- 

H- 

r+ 

rt 

«* 

•v-' 

„!« 

@ 

rt 

N—' 

•       • 

ON  -^ 


O  O 
O  O 
O  U> 

•c-  o 


CD 


VO 
W 


/-v  M 


•       • 
M  4S 

•       • 
O  O 

00  ^ 

O  O 

M  00 

O  O 

o  w 

00  00 

VO   "vl 

o\  M 

vj  o 

OJ  00 

!-■  00 

u>  *- 

00  «sl 


•      • 
H  O 
On  CTv 

VO  O 


to  wi 
ro  to 

00  CTi 


O  O 
O  O 
M  to 
O  -vj 


O  VO 

00  ^ 


j<~«  to 

•     • 

-si  l-> 
U>  VO 

00  ON 


•       • 

to  to 

•      « 

o  o 

•       • 
00  W 

l-n  to 

o  o 

00  M 

(J)  W 

*-■  CO 

O^  -sj 

*-  to 

M  CO 

U1   00 

ON    ON 

*-  OS 
to  Ul 


■>  to 

to  VO 

W  I-" 

to  o 


O  VO 
to  to 

W    ON 


to 


to 

M  O    ►< 

a  en 
rr  rt 

cr 
w 


to 


to 


t 


_      B 

3    rt 
rt 


rt 
l» 
rt 

O 

o 

(0 

r5 


u> 


^^  so 

to  pi 


o 


lO 

•>  g  H 
O  (0 
0  rt 
rt 

tr 

0) 


to 


v^ 


o 

0 

n 
rt 

(t> 
rt 

I 

M 


o 
to 

or* 


to 

C/1 


o 
-p- 


en  » 
N--  rt 
On  "-^  H* 
-^  O 

M> 


rt   6j 
O   rt 


ON 


»t3 

H 

O 

• 

V 

H 

fo 

Ui 

C 

VO 

H- 

t~^ 

H- 

rt 

v<J 

5 

C/1 


-19- 

Moving  to  the  changes  in  the  standard  deviation  of  the  change  in 
the  yield  to  maturity,  the  instability  of  the  change  in  the  yield  to 
maturity  increased  for  both  groups  of  bonds.   (This  is  to  be  expected 
because  of  the  shorter  average  maturity  of  all  bonds  in  the  last  period 
relative  to  the  first  period.   In  addition,  the  wider  dispersion  In 
corporate  bond  returns   in  the  last  period  relative  to  the  first 
period  may  also  contribute  to  the  increase  in  the  observed  standard 
deviations.)  However,  the  important  point  concerning  the  standard  de- 
viations is  that  the  standard  deviation  of  the  nonstationary  bonds 
increased  relatively  more  (1.291  to  1.064)  than  for  bonds  with  stationary 
bond  betas.   We  believe  the  primary  reason  for  the  higher  relative  stan- 
dard deviation  for  the  bonds  with  nonstationary  betas  is  due  to  the  higher 
coupon  rates  and  associated  higher  yields  to  maturity  for  the  nonstationary 
bonds.   (Not  only  do  the  nonstationary  bonds  have  higher  average  coupon 
rates,  but  they  also  have  lower  average  bond  ratings.   It  is  well  known, 
ceteris  paribus  that  the  yield  to  maturity  on  lower  rated  bonds  are  larger 
than  for  higher  rated  bonds.)  As  interest  rates  in  general  fluctuate,  the 
changes  in  the  yield  to  maturity  is  larger  for  the  nonstationary  bonds 
(which  have  higher  average  coupon  rates  and  lower  bond  ratings);  hence, 

they  have  larger  relative  standard  deviations  than  bonds  with  stationary 

12 
betas.    Thus,  the  most  important  factor  identified  in  this  study 

which  differentiates  between  bonds  with  stationary  betas  versus  those 

with  nonstationary  betas  is  the  relative  standard  deviations  in  the  changes 

in  the  yield  to  maturity.  Higher  coupon  rates  and  yields  to  maturity 

(leading  to  larger  standard  deviation  in  the  changes  in  the  yield  to 

maturity)  are  associated  with  bonds  having  nonstationary  betas. 


-20- 

Finally,  it  is  noted  that  the  correlation  between  the  changes  in 
the  yield  to  maturity  and  the  return  on  the  market  decreased  for  both 
stationary  and  nonstationary  bonds  from  the  first  to  the  last  periods. 
This  is  as  expected  since  the  sampled  bonds  in  the  third  period  have 
shorter  maturities  and  hence  their  yields  tend  to  move  less  with  the  re- 
turns on  the  market  which  are  influenced  by  common  stock  as  well  as  bond 

13 
returns.    While  not  significantly  different  (at  the  .15  level),  the  ab- 
solute value  of  p(dy.^,R  ^)  tended  to  be  lower  over  time  for  the  non- 
it  mt 

stationary  bonds  (.6875  to  .8847)  than  for  bonds  with  stationary  betas. 
Again,  this  difference  appears  to  be  due  to  the  higher  coupon  rates  and 
yield  to  maturity  carried  by  the  nonstationary  group  of  bonds  relative 
to  the  stationary  bonds. 

In  order  to  test  the  overall  ability  of  the  three  hypothesized  fac- 
tors to  differentiate  between  bonds  with  stationary  betas  and  those  with 

2 
nonstationary  betas,  Hotellings  T  was  employed.  It  resulted  in  an 

F  ratio  of  2.22  which,  with  3  and  80  degrees  of  freedom,  has  a  probability 

value  of  .091.  Thus,  at  the  10  percent  significance  level  the  three 

hypothesized  factors  (in  combination)  differentiated  between  bonds  with 

stationary  betas  and  those  with  non-stationary  betas. 

V.   SUMMARY  AND  CONCLUSIONS 
Recently  a  number  of  researchers  have  attempted  to  employ  the  market 
model  to  estimate  systematic  risk  (i.e.,  beta)  for  bonds.  In  this  study 
we  reviewed  theoretical  evidence  which  suggests  bond  betas  can  be  expected 
to  be  nonstationary.  This  nonstationarity  is  a  function  of  the  duration 
of  a  bond,  the  standard  deviation  of  the  change  in  the  yield  to  maturity 


-21- 

of  a  bond  relative  to  the  standard  deviation  of  the  return  on  the  market 
portfolio,  and  the  correlation  between  the  change  in  the  yield  to  maturity 
of  a  bond  and  the  return  on  the  market  portfolio.  However,  all  bonds 
will  not  necessarily  have  nonstationary  betas  in  a  given  time  period  since 
it  is  possible  that  these  factors  may  occasionally  counteract  one  another. 
Empirical  tests  indicated  that  over  80  percent  of  the  bonds  examined 
had  nonstationary  betas.   The  primary  factor  differentiating  bonds  with 
nonstationary  betas  from  those  with  stationary  betas  was  the  substantially 
higher  relative  standard  deviation  in  the  change  in  the  yield  to  maturity 
for  bonds  with  nonstationary  betas.   The  larger  standard  deviation  was 
caused  by  the  higher  average  coupon  rates  and  yields  to  maturity  for  bonds 
with  nonstationary  betas.   The  substantial  presence  of  nonstationarity 
in  public  utility  bond  betas  is  caused  by  the  peculiar  nature  of  long  term 
financing  in  the  public  utility  industry  which  results  in  generally  higher 
coupon  rates  and  yields  to  maturity  than  in  the  industrial  sector.   The 
theoretical  and  empirical  results  of  this  study  indicate  bond  betas,  in 
general,  tend  to  be  nonstationary.  Hence,  further  use  of  them  appears 
to  be  of  very  questionable  value. 


-22- 

FOOTNOTES 

Livingston  [18]  extended  Boquist  et  al.'s  work  by  taking  into 
account  the  duration  of  both  the  security  and  the  market  portfolio. 
He  shows  that: 

D^   P(dy,,,dR^pa(dy^^) 

where  D   is  the  duration  of  the  market  portfolio  and  dR   is  the 
change  xn  the  return  on  the  market  portfolio.  Since  the  duration  of 
the  market  portfolio  (which  is  dominated  by  common  stocks  with  infinite 
maturity)  does  not  change  much  over  time  we  have  chosen  to  work  with 
equation  (4).  The  notation  follows  that  of  Boquist  et  al.  [4]  and 
Livingston  [18]  except  y,  ,  rather  than  r.  ,  is  used  for  the  yield 
to  maturity, 

2 
To  provide  some  empirical  evidence  for  the  proposition  that 

-p(dy.  ,R  )  is  smaller  for  shorter-term  bonds  than  for  longer-term 

bonds  we  computed  -p(dy.  ,R  )  using  basic  yields  on  corporate  bonds 

with  1,  5,  10,  and  15  years^'to  maturity.  Over  the  time  period  of  1941- 

1970  the  value  of  -p(dy.  ,R  )  are  .47,  .52,  .55  and  .56  for  bonds 

with  1,  5,  10,  and  15  years'^'to  maturity,  respectively.  Therefore,  as 

expected,  -p(dy,  ,R  )  becomes  smaller  the  shorter  the  term  to 

maturity. 

3 
The  requirement  that  the  bonds  be  consistently  rated  (without 

any  change  in  rating)  insures  that  the  relative  risk  of  default  (as  per- 
ceived by  the  two  major  rating  agencies  did  not  change  over  the  time 
period  employed.  Thus,  even  though  the  bonds  are  not  default  free  as 
required  by  the  Boquist  et  al.'s  model  presented  in  equation  (4),  the 
relative  probability  of  default  was  held  constant. 

Recent  theoretical  work  by  Merton  [23],  Black  and  Cox  [3]  and 
Brennan  and  Schwartz  [5]  suggests  that  subordination  or  specific  bond 
Indenture  provisions  influence  the  value  of  bonds.  Subordination  is  not 
a  problem  since  all  bonds  selected  for  this  study  are  non-subordinated. 
In  addition,  an  examination  of  the  call  provision  indicated  that  the 
vast  majority  of  Issues  required  a  five  year  delay  if  they  were  to  be 
called  for  refunding  at  a  rate  appreciably  lower  than  the  bond's  coupon 
rate.  Given  the  general  rise  in  interest  rates  during  this  time  period 
there  was  no  economic  incentive  to  refund.  Finally,  virtually  all  of 
the  industrial  bonds  and  a  small  portion  of  the  public  utility  bonds  are 
debentures.  While  some  minor  differences  in  the  characteristics  of  the 
bonds  examined  exist,  there  is  no  reason  to  believe  that  any  systematic 
tendencies  are  present  which  influence  the  results. 


-23- 

A  list  of  84  bonds  Is  available  from  the  authors.  The  primary 
source  of  the  monthly  price  data  (for  the  period  May  31,  1969  through 
May  31,  1975)  was  the  Bank  and  Quotation  Record  [1].  Secondary  sources  in- 
cluded Commercial  and  Financial  Chronicle  [8],  Moody's  Bond  Record  [24] 
and  Standard  and  Poor's  Bond  Guide  [321.  The  closing  bid  or  sale  price 
was  employed;  however,  it  occasionally  became  necessary  to  use  an  opening 
ask  price.  The  availability  of  data  was  less  of  a  problem  for  the  public 
utility  bonds  than  for  the  industrials  in  that  closing  bid  or  sale  prices 
were  almost  uniformly  available  for  the  public  utility  issues  examined. 
Other  features  of  the  bonds  were  deteirmined  by  reference  to  Moody's  Public 
Utility  [26]  and  Moody's  Industrial  [25]  manuals. 

The  common  stock  returns  employed  were  those  from  the  CRSP  value- 
weighted  index  while  the  corporate  and  government  bond  returns  were  those 
(as  updated)  provided  by  Ibbotson  and  Sinquefleld  [16].  The  common  stock 
weights  employed  were  obtained  from  the  Statistical  Bulletin  [33]  while 
the  corporate  and  government  bond  weights  were  obtained  from  the  Economic 
Report  of  the  President  [11].  It  can  be  shown  that  the  use  of  a  common 
stock  index  for  R   will  result  in  lower  estimated  bond  betas.  We 
conducted  part  of™the  analysis  with  the  CRSP  values-weighted  index— there 
were  no  significant  differences  between  those  results  and  the  reported 
findings. 

We  also  examined  the  statlonary/nonstationarlty  of  a.  and 
3.  simultaneously  as  estimated  by  equation  (1) .  The  subsequent  find- 
ings are  virtually  the  same  whether  we  focus  on  the  statlonarity  of  both 
a.  and  3^  as  estimated  by  equation  (1)  or  only  the  statlonarity 
or  3j  as  estimated  by  equation  (6) . 

o 

The  computer  program  to  test  the  statlonarity  of  3  is  pro- 
vided by  BDE  [7]. 

9 
The  bond  betas  did  vary  by  bond  rating  group  with  a  mean  of  0.570 

for  the  Aaa/AAA  group,  0.450  for  the  Aa/AA  group,  0.391  for  the  A/A  group 

and  0.372  for  the  Baa/BBB  group.  A  one-way  analysis  of  variance  yielded 

an  F-ratlo  of  2.87  which,  with  3  and  80  degrees  of  freedom,  was  significant 

at  the  .041  level.  Schwendlman  and  Pinches  [30]  reported  that  mean  common 

stock  betas  Increased  as  bond  ratings  decreased;  our  results  indicated 

that  bond  betas  decrease  as  bond  ratings  decrease.  While  the  instability 

of  the  bond  betas  casts  serious  doubt  on  the  interpretablllty  of  bond 

betas,  there  appears  to  be  no  consistency  between  bond  betas,  common  stock 

betas  and  bond  ratings.  No  other  material  differences  are  noted  in  the 

sample. 

Since  duration  changes  each  period,  we  calculated  duration  at 
the  middle  of  the  first  time  period  (month  12)  and  the  middle  of  the 
third  time  period  (month  60). 

'xhe  standard  deviation  of  returns  on  corporate  bonds,  using 
the  Ibbotson  and  Sinquefleld  [16]  data,  was  .0290  for  the  first  time 
period  and  .0309  for  the  last  time  period.  Hence,  bond  returns  in  gen- 
eral were  more  volatile  in  the  last  time  period. 


-24- 

12 

As  an  example  of  the  relationship  between  bond  ratings  and  stan- 
dard deviation  of  the  change  in  yield  to  maturity,  weekly  yields  to 
maturity  were  gathered  for  Standard  and  Poor's  AAA.,  AA,  A  and  BBB  in- 
dustrial and  public  utility  bonds  from  July  through  December  1977.  The 
standard  deviations  of  the  change  in  yield  to  maturity  for  the  four 
bond  groups  over  that  time  period  were: 

Industrial— AAA  -  .0393,  AA  -  .0428,  A  -  .0510,  BBB  -  .1962;  and 
Public  Utility— AAA  -  .0415,  Aa  -  .0422,  A  -  .0441,  BBB  -  .0527.   In  all 
cases  the  standard  deviation  in  the  changes  in  the  yield  to  maturity  in- 
crease as  the  bond  ratings  decrease. 

13 

See  footnote  2. 


-25- 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


1.  Bank  and  Quotation  Record.  New  York:  William  B.  Daner  Co.,  1969-1975. 

2.  F.  Black.   "Capital  Market  Equilibrium  with  Restricted  Borrowing," 
Journal  of  Business,  Volume  45  (July  1972),  pp.  444-454, 

3.  F.  Black  and  J.  C.  Cox.   "Valuing  Corporate  Securities:   Some  Effects 
of  Bond  Indenture  Provisions,"  Journal  of  Finance,  Volume  31 

(May  1976),  pp.  351-367. 

4.  J.  A.  Boquist,  G.  A.  Racette  and  G.  G.  Schlarbaum.   "Duration  and  Risk 
Assessment  for  Bonds  and  Common  Stocks,"  Journal  of  Finance, 

Vol.  30  (December  1975),  pp.  1360-1365. 

5.  M.  J.  Brennan  and  E.  S.  Schwartz.   "Savings  Bonds,  Retractable  Bonds 
and  Callable  Bonds,"  Journal  of  Financial  Economics,  Vol.  5 
(August,  1977),  pp.  67-88. 

6.  R.  L.  Brown  and  J.  Durbin.   "Models  of  Investigating  Whether  a  Regression 
Relationship  is  Constant  Over  Time,"  Selected  Statistical  Papers, 
European  Meeting,  Mathematical  Centre  Tracts  Number  26,  Amsterdam, 

1968. 

7.  R.  L.  Brown,  J.  Durbin  and  J.  M.  Evans.   "Techniques  for  Testing  the 
Constancy  of  Regression  Relationships  Over  Time,"  Journal  of  the 
Royal  Statistical  Society,  Vol.  27  (1975),  pp.  149-192. 

8.  Commercial  and  Financial  Chronicle,  Various  Issues. 

9.  J.  Durbin.   "Tests  for  Serial  Correlation  in  Regression  Analysis  Based 
on  the  Periodogram  of  Least  Squares  Residuals,"  Blometrika,  Vol.  38 
(1968),  pp.  1-15. 

10.  R.  M.  Duval  1  and  J.  M.  Cheney.   "The  Relationship  of  Bond  Yi,elds  to 
Capital  Structure  When  Bankruptcy  is  Possible."  A  paper  presented 
at  the  Financial  Management  Association  Meeting,  Seattle,  1977. 

11.  Economic  Report  of  the  President,  United  States  Government,  Washington, 
D.C.,  1978,  p.  337. 

12.  A.  R.  Eddy.   "Interest  Rate  Risk  and  Systematic  Risk:   An  Interpretation," 
Journal  of  Finance,  Vol.   33  (May  1978),  pp.  626-630. 

13.  L.  Fisher.   "An  Algorithm  for  Finding  Exact  Rates  of  Return,"  Journal 
of  Business  (January  1966),  pp.  111-118. 

14.  I.  Friend  and  M.  E.  Blume.   "The  Demand  for  Risky  Assets,"  American 
Economic  Review,  Vol.  65  (December  1975),  pp.  900-922. 


.-.Olc, 


-26- 


15.  M.  H.  Hopewell  and  G.  G.  Kaufman.   "Bond  Price  Volatility  and  Term  to 
Maturity:   A  Generalized  Representation,"  American  Economic  Review, 
Vol.  63  (September  1973),  pp.  749-753. 

16.  R.  G.  Ibbotson  and  R.  H.  Sinquefield,   "Stocks,  Bonds,  Bills  and  Infla- 
tion: Year-by-Year  Historical  Returns  (1926-74),"  Journal  of 
Business,  Vol.  49  (January  1976),  pp.  11-47. 

17.  J.  Lintner.   "The  Valuation  of  Risk.  Assets  and  the  Selection  of  Risky 
Investments  in  Stock  Portfolios  and  Capital  Budget,"  Review  of 
Economics  and  Statistics,  Vol.  47  (Feburary  1966),  pp.  13-37. 

18.  M.  Livingston.   "Duration  and  Risk  Assessment  for  Bonds  and  Common  Stocks: 
A  Note,"  Journal  of  Finance,  Vol.  33  (March  1978),  pp.  293-295. 

19.  F.  R.  Macaulay.   "Some  Theoretical  Problems  Suggested  by  the  Movements 
of  Interest  Rates,  Bond  Yields  and  Stock  Prices  in  the  United 

States  Since  1856,"  New  York:   National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research, 
1938,  pp.  45-53. 

20.  B.  G,  Malkiel.   The  Term  Structure  of  Interest  Rates.   Princeton,  1966. 

21.  J.  S.  McCallum.   "The  Expected  Holding  Period  Return,  Uncertainty 
and  the  Term  Structure  of  Interest  Rates,"  Journal  of  Finance, 
Vol.  30  (May  1975),  pp.  307-323. 

22.  C.  B.  Mehr  and  J.  A.  McFadden.   "Certain  Properties  of  Gaussian  Processes 
and  Their  First  Passage  Time,"  Journal  of  the  Royal  Statistical 
Society,  Series  B,  Vol.  27  (1965),  pp.  505-522. 

23.  R.  C.  Merton.   "On  the  Pricing  of  Corpoorate  Debt:  The  Risk  Structure 
of  Interest  Rates,"  Journal  of  Finance,  Vol.  29  (May  1974),  pp. 
449-470. 

24.  Moody's  Bond  Record.  New  York:  Moody's  Investors  Services,  1969-1975. 

25.  Moody's  Industrial  Manual.  New  York:   Moody's  Investors  Services, 
1968-1976. 

26.  Moody's  Public  Utility  Manual.   New  York:   Moody's  Investors  Services, 
1968-1976. 

27.  J.  Percival.   "Corporate  Bonds  in  a  Market  Model  Context,"  Journal  of 
Business  Research  (October  1974),  pp.  461-468. 

28.  F.  K.  Reilly  and  M.  Joehnk.   "The  Association  Between  Market- 
Determined  Risk  Measures  for  Bonds  and  Bond  Ratings,"  Journal  of 
Finance,  Vol.  31  (December  1976),  pp.  1387-1403. 

29.  R.  Roll.   "A  Critique  of  the  Asset  Pricing  Theory's  Test  Part  I:   On 
Past  and  Potential  Testability  of  the  Theory,"  Journal  of  Financial 
Economics,  Vol.  4,  No.  2  (March  1977),  pp.  127-176. 


-27- 


30.  C.  J.  Schwendiman  and  G.  E.  Pinches.   "An  Analysis  of  Alternative 
Measures  of  Investment  Risk,"  Journal  of  Finance,  Vol.  30  (March 
1975),  pp.  183-200. 

31.  W.  F.  Sharpe.   "Capital  Asset  Prices:  A  Theory  of  Market  Equilibrium 
Under  Conditions  of  Risk,"  Journal  of  Finance,  Vol.  19  (September 
1964),  pp.  425-442. 

32.  Standard  &  Poor's  Bond  Guide.  New  York:   Standard  &  Poor's  Corp., 
1968-1975. 

33.  U.S.  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission.   Statistical  Bulletin,  Vol.  36 
(June  1977),  p.  9.  Washington:   U.S.  Government  Printing  Office. 

34.  J.  B.  Warner.   "Bankruptcy,  Absolute  Priority  and  the  Pricing  of  Risky 
Debt  Claims,"  Journal  of  Financial  Economics,  Vol.  4  (May  1977), 

pp.  239-276. 

35.  J.  B.  Yawitz.   "The  Relative  Importance  of  Duration  and  Yield  Volatility 
on  Bond  Price  Volatility,"  Journal  of  Money,  Credit  and  Banking, 

Vol.  9  (February  1977),  pp.  97-102. 

36.  J.  B.  Yawitz  and  W.  J.  Marshall.   "Risk  and  Return  in  the  Government 
Bond  Market,"  Journal  of  Portfolio  Management  (Summer  1977), 

pp.  48-52. 

( 


M/E/103 


j-94