Skip to main content

Full text of "The optimal accumulation of human capital over the life cycle"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

AT  URE3  i  IA-CHAMPAIGN 

u  ^»_  rf\o  i  AC.O 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/optimalaccumulat553grah 


Faculty  Working  Papers 


College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 

University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPERS 
College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 
March  22,  1979 


THE  OPTIMAL  ACCUMULATION  OF  HUMAN  CAPITAL  OVER 
THE  LIFE  CYCLE 

John  Graham,  Assistant  Professor,  Department  of 
Economics 

#553 


Summary; 

This  paper  summarizes  the  important  contributions  of  the  new  life  cycle  human 
capital  literature  and  demonstrates  that  many  of  these  results  can  be  derived 
more  simply  than  in  their  original  presentations.   Within  three  period  discrete- 
time  framework  it  is  demonstrated  how  the  optimal  pattern  of  human  capital  in- 
vestment over  the  life  cycle  depends  upon  the  choice  of  the  objective  function, 
the  life  cycle  of  leisure,  and  the  extent  of  nonmarket  benefits  of  human 
capital.   The  paper  offers  sufficient  conditions  for  the  optimality  of  a  profile 
of  monotonically  declining  investment  activity  over  the  life  cycle. 


The  Optimal  Accumulation  of  Human  Capital  Over  the  Life  Cycle 
I.   Introduction 

Although  formal  modeling  of  the  process  of  human  capital  accu- 
mulation has  been  going  on  for  some  15  years  now,  the  development  of 
such  models  within  an  explicit  life  cycle  context  has  a  far  shorter 
history.  Even  as  late  as  1976,  Blaug's  comprehensive  survey  of  the 
field  offers  no  discussion  of  human  capital  accumulation  over  the 
life  cycle.   Only  since  then  have  several  articles  appeared  that 

attempt  to  solve  for  the  optimal  life  time  pattern  of  human  capital 

2 
investment.   This  paper  summarizes  the  important  results  of  this  new 

literature  and  demonstrates  that  most  of  these  results  can  be  derived 

more  simply  than  in  their  original  presentations  and  without  some 

special  assumptions  previously  imposed.  Finally,  this  paper  offers 

sufficient  conditions  for  the  optimality  of  a  profile  of  declining 

investment  time  ever  the  life  cycle. 

Early  models  of  human  capital  accumulation  were  either  static,  or 

3 
if  dynamic,  ignored  the  constraints  imposed  by  the  life  cycle.   The 

development  of  models  within  a  life  cycle  context  represent  a  major 
advance  for  several  reasons.  First,  the  life  cycle  lends  added  realism 
to  models  of  optimal  accumulation.   It  forces  the  model  builder  to  incor- 
porate several  essential  characteristics  of  human  capital  investment 
that  set  it  apart  from  other  forms  of  consumer  saving ;as  well  as  from 
other  types  of  physical  investment.  Unlike  many  other  forms  of  consumer 
saving,  acquisition  of  human  capital  is  irreversible.  Bonds  acquired 
today  can  be  sold  tomorrow,  but  human  capital  acquired  today  cannot  be 
so  easily  liquidated.  By  incorporating  the  process  of  aging,  life  cycle 


-2- 

models  make  explicity  the  necessarily  sequential  and  one-directional 
nature  of  human  capital  accumulation.   Unlike  investment  in  most 
physical  capital,  investment  in  human  capital  is  subject  to  constraints 
on  the  magnitude  of  accumulation.  With  perfect  financal  markets,  firms 

can  acquire  as  much  capital  as  they  want  to  during  any  period,  but 

4 
consumers  cannot  always  acquire  as  much  human  capital  as  they  desire. 

The  reason  is  that  human  capital  is  not  purchased  in  the  market  at  a 

constant  price,  but  "produced"  by  the  consumer  with  his  finite  resource 

of  time.  Since  there  exists  no  market  in  which  more  of  this  time  input 

can  be  acquired  immediately,  the  only  alternative  is  to  postpone  some 

investment  until  the  future. 

One  benefit  of  studying  human  capital  within  a  life  cycle 
context  is  that  an  examination  of  the  pattern  of  accumulation  that 
emerges  can  provide  a  check  on  the  internal  consistency  of  the  model. 
For  example,  one  should  become  wary  of  putting  too  much  faith  in  the 
policy  prescriptions  that  follow  from  a  model  in  which  monotonically 
increasing  investment  over  the  life  cycle  emerges  as  the  optimal 
pattern  of  investment. 

Casual  observation  suggests  that  the  most  common  pattern  of  human 
capital  accumulation  is  a  declining  profile  of  investment  time  vrtrt   the 
life  cycle.   Therefore,  it  should  be  interesting  to  investigate  the 
conditions  under  which  such  a  pattern  is  indeed  optimal.  Additionally, 
one  would  hope  that  a  model  might  provide  insight  into  other  patterns 
of  accumulation.  How  can  one  explain  the  not  uncommon  pattern  of  a 
return  to  full-time  schooling  after  a  period  of  full-time  work?  Is 


-3- 

such  behavior  simply  irrational,  or  is  it  possible  to  provide  a  choice- 
theoretic  framework  in  which  this  behavior  emerges  as  both  rational 
and  optimal? 

It  is  important  at  this  stage  to  interject  a  word  of  caution. 
While  it  is  tempting  to  equate  human  capital  accumulation  with  school- 
ing, it  is  wrong  to  do  so.   The  models  developed  in  this  paper  and 
in  the  related  literature  take  a  broader  view.  Human  capital  accu- 
mulation is  defined  as  all  non-costless  current  activity  that  enhances 
the  value  of  future  time.   Thus,  it  includes  not  only  schooling,  but 
also  on-the-job  training  and  investment  in  health  or  information. 
Viewed  in  this  wider  context,  it  is  not  even  clear  that  the  "normal" 
life  cycle  pattern  has  investment  time  declining  with  age. 

II.  Human  Capital  in  the  Life  Cycle  Literature 

The  first  dynamic   theories  of  optimal  human  capital  accumulation 
due  to  Ben-Porath  and  Becker  represented  significant  advances  over   the 
existing  static  models,   but  even  they  ignored  any  explicit  life  cycle 
consideration.     In  other  words,  neither  assumed   the  consumer   to  be  making 
choices   that  would  maximize  lifetime  utility  subject   to   the  constraints 
of  age,   lifetime  income  and   intertemporal  prices.      Instead,    the  under- 
lying hypothesis  maintained  by  both  Becker  and  Ben-Porath  was   that  indi- 
viduals would  select  a  lifetime  plan  for  human  capital  investment  to 
maximize  total  lifetime  income,    and   then  at  some  later  stage  would  maxi- 
mize lifetime  utility  subject  to   this  value  of   lifetime  income.      It  is 
exactly   this  recursive  two-step  maximization  that  the  recent  life  cycle 
human  capital  literature  demonstrates   to  be  invalid.     According  to  Ryder, 
Stafford  and  Stephen: 


-4- 


The  criterion  of  maximal  present  value  for  investment 
decisions  is  usually  justified  by  what  Hirshleifer  terms 
the  Separation  Theorem.   That  is,  'given  perfect  and  com- 
plete markets,  the  productive  decision  is  to  be  governed 
solely  by  the  objective  market  criterion  represented  by 
attained  wealth — without  regard  to  the  individual's  subjec- 
tive preferences  that  enter  into  their  consumption  deci- 
sions.' Unlike  physical  capital,  however,  human  capital 
is  embodied  in  the  human  being  and,  hence,  in  the  unit 
that  makes  decisions  about  the  life-cycle  allocation  of 
time.  One  implication  of  this  is  that  whenever  time  has 
an  alternative  use  that  produces  utility  the  separation- 
theorem  holds  only  if  restrictive  assumptions  are  made. 

Unfortunately  the  gain  in  realism  provided  by  utility  maximization 
in  a  life  cycle  context  has  not  been  coscless.  When  consumption  and 
investment  decisions  are  interrelated,  the  consumer's  maximization  prob- 
lem is  very  difficult  to  solve  in  general  and  even  particular  functional 
forms  rarely  provide  closed  form  solutions.  To  obtain  any  meaningful 
results,  the  literature  has  been  forced  to  impose  potentially  severe 
simplifying  assump*  ■,~~s.  For  example,  to  obtain  interpretable  life 
cycle  paths  for  leisure,  invertnient  and  work  time,  Ryder,  Stafford,  and 
Stephen  assume  that  the  lifetime  utility  function  can  be  written  in 
logarithmic  form.  Cinder  and  Weiss  do  not  choose  particular  functional 
forms,  but  they  do  assume  that  their  utility  function  exhibits  separ- 
ability of  time  ani  roods  at-  erch  io.stauc  of  time.  Furthermore,  their 
production  function  for  human  capital  is  assumed  homogeneous  of  degree 
one  in  the  input  of  time;  in  other  words,  doubling  the  time  devoted  to 
investment  doubles  the  output  of  human  capital  produced.   Finally,  in 
Heckman's  papers  the  existing  stock  of  human  capital  enters  both  the 
utility  and  production  functions  in  a  very  special  way  which  Heckman 
dubs  the  "neutrality  hypothesis."  According  to  this  specification, 


-5- 

additions  to  the  stock,  of  human  capital  equally  augments  the  efficiency 
of  all  uses  of  time — work,  leisure,  and  investment. 

In  this  study  we  first  extend  the  work  of  Ryder,  Stafford  and 
Stephen  to  examine  how  the  optimal  lire  cycle  profile  of  human  capital 
accumulation  depends  upon  the  objective  function  of  the  consumer.   In 
Section  III  we  derive  the  optimal  investment  profile  for  a  wealth  maxi- 
mizer,  and  in  Section  IV  the  optimal  profile  for  a  utility  maximizer. 
Unlike  earlier  work  our  utility  function  is  general  in  form  and  does 
not  assume  separability  of  commodities  within  a  given  period.  Our  pro- 
duction function  exhibits  diminishing  returns  to  the  time  input.  In 
Section  V  we  extend  Heckman's  results  by  allowing  for  non-neutral  in- 
fluences of  human  capital  on  the  efficiency  of  alternative  uses  of  time 
by  introducing  a  leisure  technology  parameter.  We  examine  what  influence 
this  parameter  has  on  the  profile  of  Investment  time.   Throughout  the 
paper  the  results  are  expressed  In  terms  of  sufficient  conditions  for 
the  optimality  of  a  "normal"  declining  investment  time  profile  over  the 
life  cycle. 

III.  Optimal  Accumulation  Within  a  Wealth-Maximization.  Model 

Suppose  an  individual  expects  with  certainty  to  live  for  three 
identical  and  consecutive  discrete  time  periods.   During  each  per- 
iod he  must  allocate  his  predetermined  nonleisure  time  between  two 
activities — work  time  which  earns  a  monetary  reward  and  human  capi- 
tal investment  time  which  enhances  the  value  of  future  work  time. 
Let  K.  denote  the  fraction  of  time  during  period  i  devoted  to  in- 
vestment. The  individual  Is  endowed  with  an  initial  earnings  potential 


-6- 


Hn  which  can  be  augmented  through  human  capital  production  according 
to  the  transition  equation 

H±  -  H^  -  F(Kt)  (1) 

For  simplicity,  assume  the  production  function  F  satisfies  the  Inada 
conditions.   Assume  that  work  time  yields  a  return  to  the  existing 
stock  of  human  capital  at  the  constant  rental  rate  w.   Therefore  first 
period  earnings  equal  wH^l-K.),  that  iss  the  return  on  the  initial 
stock  of  human  capital,  wH»,  times  the  length  of  noninvestment  time, 
(1-K.).  Second  period  earnings  equal  wH..(l-K_),  where  the  new  stock 
of  human  capital  is  obtained  from  equation  (1)  as  determined  by  the 
first  period's  investment  activity.  Finally,  third  period  earnings 
equal  wH-  •  K-  equals  zero  since  returns  to  any  third  period  invest- 
ment would  not  accrue  until  after  the  terminal  date.  The  choice  problem 
for  the  individual  is  to  select  K.  and  K?  to  maximize  wealth,  or 
discounted  lifetime  income: 

(l+r)2wH()(l-K1)  +  (l+rJwH^l-Kp  +  wH2 

where  H^  and  H2  are  defined  in  equation  (1),  and  r  is  the  interest 
rate  in  the  perfect  financial  capital  market.  Assuming  interior  so- 
lutions, wealth  is  maximized  when 


§;  -  (l+r)Hl  (2) 


(1^)(1-V%  +  %=<14t>2ho    '  <3> 


-7- 

*      * 

The  equations  can  be  solved,  in  principle,  for  ]L.    and  K_,  the  optimal 

fractions  of  nonleisure  time  devoted  to  human  capital  accumulation. 
Together  these  equations  represent  the  familiar  requirement  that  in- 
vestment time  be  chosen  to  equate  the  marginal  cost  of  production  (on 
the  right  hand  side)  with  its  discounted  lifetime  marginal  benefits 
(on  the  left  hand  side) . 

To  evaluate  the  life  cycle  pattern  of  investment  time  in  this  model 
it  is  sufficient  to  compare  K.  to  L.  At  this  point  it  should  be  clear 
why  we  have  selected  a  three  period  life  cycle.  With  K  =0,  three  periods 
represent  the  minimum  life  cycle  needed  to  compare  two  unconstrained 
periods.   In  principle  the  analysis  could  be  extended  to  any  number  of 
discrete  periods. 

We  shall  prove  and  then  discuss  the  following  theorem. 

Theorem  One;  YL    >   K~  is  the  only  feasible  investment 
path  that  satisfies  (2)  and  (3). 

We  proceed  with  a  proof  by  contradiction.   Suppose  K=K  =K.  Then 

dF    dF    dF 

~-  -  •—-  =  —;.     Combine  (2)  and  (3)  to  obtain: 

7 
(1-H:)2(1-K)K1  +  (l-fr)^  =  (l+r)2H0  (4) 

It  is  straightforward  to  show  that  (4)  cannot  hold  with  equality. 
To  see  this,  differentiate  the  left  hand  side  of  (4)  with  respect 
to  K  obtaining 

(l+r)2(l-K)  j[| 

which  is  nonnegative  for  0  <_  K  <_  1.  Therefore,  the  left  hand  side  of 
(4)  is  an  increasing  function  of  K.  Evaluating  this  expresion  at 


-8- 

K-0,  its  smallest  value,  yields  (l+r)Tl0  +  (l+r)HQ.  Since  this  al- 
ready exceeds  the  value  of  the  right  hand  side,  (4)  cannot  hold  with 
equality  for  any  0  <_  K  <_  1.  Therefore,  the  assumption  K^*^  ^as  *e(*  t0 

a  contradiction. 

dF    dF 
Now  suppose  K?  >  1L.  .   This  implies  that  -tjt-  <  ^7~.  Now  when  (2) 

dF 
is  substituted  into  (3),  -rrr-    must  be  replaced  by  even  more  than  (14r)H..  . 

This  only  makes  the  left  hand  side  of  (4)  larger,  so  the  contradition 

stands. 

dF    dF 
Finally,  suppose  K-  >  K„.   This  means  -tz-  <   -rr-,  so  when  substituting 

(2)  into  (3),  -Tjr-  will  be  replaced  by  less  than  (l+r)H..  This  is  the 

only  case  for  which  equality  in  (4)  can  possibly  hold.  For  some  K, 

K.  >  K_  does  not  imply  a  contradiction.   Q.E.D. 

The  importance  of  Theorem  One  is  that  it  demonstrates  that  aside 

from  an  ad  hoc  change  in  the  form  of  production  function  for  human 

capital  over  the  life  cycle,  there  is  no  way  to  explain  a  nonde- 

creasing  investment  profile  when  individuals  select  investment  time 

to  maximize  lifetime  wealth.  Intuitively,  investments  are  made 

early  rather  than  late  in  life  for  two  reasons.  First,  the  earlier 

the  investment  is  undertaken,  the  greater  are  the  remaining  number  of 

periods  for  the  benefits  to  accrue.   Investment  late  in  the  life 

cycle  leaves  insufficient  time  to  reap  the  benefits.  The  other  reason 

why  earlier  investment  i&  more  profitable  is  that  is  when  the  costs  of 

production  are  the  lowest.   Investment  not  only  increases  the  value  of 

future  work  time,  but  it  also  increases  the  cost  of  future  investment. 

These  rising  costs  and  declining  benefits  reinforce  each  other  to  make 

a  dedllning  life  cycle  of  investment  activity  the  only  feasible  profile. 


-9- 


IV.  Optimal  Accumulation  Within  a  Utility-Maximization  Kodel 

Assume  the  identical  set-up  to  the  previous  problem,  except 
that  now  the  individual  selects  K  to  maximize  lifetime  utility. 
This  means  he  has  several  additional  choices  to  make.  Let  I     be  the 
fraction  of  total  time  devoted  to  leisure  in  period  i,  where  leisure  is 
defined  as  all  nonwork,  noninvestment  time,  and  the  only  use  of  time 
that  yields  utility  directly.   In  addition  to  his  allocation  of  time, 
the  individual  must  decide  upon  his  pattern  of  purchases  of  goods  over 
the  life  cycle.   Let  X.  be  a  composite  nondurable  commodity  purchased 
in  period  i  at  a  price  of  one.  The  individual's  choice  problem  can 
be  summarized  as  selecting  X.. ,  X_,  X„,  £. ,  l~,    £»,  IC. ,  and  K„  to 
maximize  lifetime  utility 

u(X1,l1)  +v(X2,£2)  +  z(X3,£3), 

subject  to:   (l+r^U-JLj-K^wHg  +  (l-+r)  (l-J^-K^wl^ 

+  wH2(l-£3)  -  (l+r)^  -  (l+r)X2  -  ^   -  0 

The  only  assumption  imposed  on  preferences  is  that  the  lifetime  utility 
function  exhibits  intertemporal  separability.  The  complete  set  of 
first-order  conditions  appears  in  Appendix  A. 

Reproduced  below  are  the  two  first  order  conditions  from  Appendix 
A  for  choosing  K.  and  K_: 

it      jv 
(l-*3)  ||-=  (1+r)^  (5) 


1K2 
(l-hrMl-**-^)  3|-+  <l-*3)  f^-«  (l+r)<-H0 


dF   •  -    -**  dF  -  (l+r)2Hn  (6) 


-10- 

Like  (2)  and  (3),  these  equations  say  that  investment  time  should 
be  chosen  to  equate  foregone  marginal  costs  with  marginal  benefits. 
But  unlike  in  the  earlier  pair  of  equations,  benefits  now  depend  upon 
the  planned  life  cycle  consumption  of  leisure  time.  This  means  that 
the  optimal  profile  of  human  capital  investment  cannot  be  derived  solely 
from  the  pair  of  equations  above,  but  requires  the  two  additional  first 
order  conditions  for  leisure  in  the  second  and  third  periods.  However, 
we  shall  see  that  equations  (5)  and  (6)  by  themselves  are  sufficient 
to  obtain  a  sense  of  the  lifetime  profile  of  investment  as  long  as  we 
assume  that  the  future  time  path  of  leisure  is  always  being  chosen 
optimally  (and  denoted  Jt„  and  £„). 

The  major  result  of  this  section  is  that  Theorem  One  which  guaran- 
teed a  declining  life  cycle  of  investment  time  will  no  longer  hold  uncon- 
ditionally. When  individuals  maximize  lifetime  utility  and  not  wealth, 
for  certain  parameter  values  any  investment  profile  is  feasible.  At 
best  we  can  offer  the  following  sufficient  condition  for  the  optimality 
of  the  "normal"  decreasing  pattern  of  investment  time  over  the  life 
cycle . 

Theorem  Two:   K-  >  K_  is  the  only  feasible  investment  path  that 

*    * 

satisfies  (5)  and  (6)  if  «,  <_  I   . 

We  again  offer  a  proof  by  contradiction.  Suppose  K.=!K_=K?.  Then 

dF    dF    dF  dF 

-Ty~  =  -T7T-  ■  -j-jr  •   Substituting  from  (5)  into  (6)  to  eliminate  — ,  we 

obtain: 

* 

(1— &   -K)  ? 

(1+r)2  2_  ^  +  (i+r)^  =  (l+r)2!^  (7) 


-11- 


Dlfferentiation  of  the  left  hand  side  of  (7)  shows  that  the  expression 

Is  a  nondecreasing  function  of  K: 

* 

„  ,_x2  ^-y*0  dF  „  n 

(1+r)  ; — Hkl°- 

Now  evaluate  (7)  at  K=0,  where  the  left  hand  side  will  be  the  smal- 
lest: 

,   (l-O  ? 

(l+rr  =~  H_  +   (14r)Hn  =*    (l+r)ZHn  (8) 

(1-**)      °  °  ° 

JL  J, 

Equality  in  (8)  cannot  hold   if  £„  _<  £„,  but  it  can  possibly  hold  for 
some  £_  <   £„.     Therefore,   as  long  as  £„  <_  £„,    the  assumption  that 
Ki"Ko  leads   to  a  contradiction.     Just  as   in  the  proof   to   theorem  one, 

another  contradiction  is  reached   (given  £.  <_  £  )   if  it  is  assumed  that 

dF 
K.    <  K_  since  -r—-  in  equation  (6)  will  be  replaced  by  even  more  than 

jj —  from  equation  (5),   making  the  left  hand  side  of   (7)   even 

u-V 

larger.  Only  IL  <  K2  produces  no  contradiction.  Q.E.D. 

Theorem  Two  can  be  explained  intuitively.   The  first  order  condi- 
tions (5)  and  (6)  for  selecting  the  investment  profile  say  that  an 
important  determinant  of  human  capital  investment  is  planned  consumption 
of  leisure.   Since  returns  to  human  capital  investment  accrue  only  when 
the  individual  is  working,  the  individual's  preferences  over  leisure 
will  influence  the  extent  of  future  benefits  from  current  investment. 
It  is  easy  to  see  how  an  "abnormal"  investment  profile  might  occur.  If 
consumption  of  leisure  is  falling  and  work  time  is  increasing  over 
the  life  cycle,  the  discounted  benefits  from  investing  during  period 
two  might  be  greater  than  the  discounted  benefits  from  investing  during 


-12- 

period  one  if  the  returns  in  period  three  (large  relative  to  those  in 
period  two  because  of  the  declining  life  cycle  of  leisure  time)  are 
sufficiently  heavily  discounted. 

But,  of  course,  the  life  cycle  of  leisure  itself  is  not  indepen- 
dent of  the  individual's  production  of  human  capital.   Therefore,  it 
is  necessary  to  re-examine  the  first-order  conditions  to  see  if  a 
declining  life  cycle  of  leisure  (which  could  produce  an  increasing 
investment  profile)  is  likely  or  even  feasible.  From  Appendix  A,  the 
first  order  conditions  for  £_  and  £„  are: 

8vU9,X9) 

^  -   (Ht)wH1A  =  0  (9) 

3z(£  ,X  ) 

^     -  wfi2X  =  0  (10) 

where  A  is  the  lagrangian  multiplier  associated  with  the  budget  con- 
straint. Without  imposing  further  assumptions  on  the  form  of  the  utility 
function,  very  little  can  be  said  about  the  life  cycle  of  leisure. 
However,  if  we  are  willing  to  assume  separability  of  leisure  and  goods 
within  any  period,  and  further  to  assume  that  the  utility  function  for 
leisure  differs  across  periods  only  by  the  individual's  subjective 
rate  of  discount  which  also  equals  the  market  interest  rate  (i.e., 

rr-3  (1+r)  -rr— ) ,  then  we  can  divide  (9)  by  (10),  obtaining  the 
3£2         3*2 

condition: 

3z 

at,       a 
nr =  ST  (11) 

3*„ 


-13- 


Now  as  long  as  the  second  order  conditions  for  utility  maximization 

32z 
hold  ( — j  <   0),  then  according  to  equation  (11),  JU  is  less  than  £, 

whenever  TJ_  exceeds  H. .  Whenever  K„  is  nonzero,  £L  will  exceed  H. , 

so  leisure  consumption  will  fall  from  period  two  to  period  three.  This 

likely  occurance  is  exactly  the  circumstances  under  which  the  investment 

profile  can  be  increasing  over  some  portion  of  the  life  cycle. 


V.   Optimal  Accumulation  Within  A  Utility-Maximization  Model 
With  Consumption  Benefits  From  Human  Capital 


Robert  Michael  formalized  the  notion  that  investment  in  human 
capital  might  not  only  enhance  future  market  earnings,  but  also 
provide  direct  consumption  benefits.  We  shall  investigate  how  the 
intensity  of  such  consumption  benefits  might  influence  the  optimal 
profile  of  lifetime  human  capital  investment.  Our  particular  speci- 
fication of  consumption  benefits  of  human  capital  is  due  to  James 
Heckman. 

The  only  modification  from  the  previous  problem  is  in  the  form  of 
the  utility  function.  Let  lifetime  utility  be  written  as 

uCXj^Hj)  +  v(X2,A2H£)  +  z(X3,£3H^)  (12) 

where  intertemporal  separability  is  again  assumed  to  prevail,  but  not 
separability  of  time  and  goods  within  any  period.  Michael  suggests 
that  if  human  capital  enhances  efficiency  in  market  production,  it 
may  also  increase  the  efficiency  of  nonmarket  production.  In  (12), 
the  parameter  a_  captures  the  relative  change  in  efficiency  of  work 
time  compared  to  leisure  time.  For  a»=0,  (12)  reduces  to  the  utility 
function  of  the  previous  section  in  which  human  capital  provided  no 


-14- 

consumption  benefits.  For  a=l,  human  capital  accumulation  increases 
the  efficiency  of  both  work  and  leisure  equally.   To  see  this,  notice 
that  the  marginal  cost  of  leisure  is  constant  in  all  three  periods 
when  a=l.   In  other  words,  even  though  the  market  wage  increases  as 
a  result  of  investment,  the  opportunity  cost  of  leisure  time  remains 
unchanged  because  leisure  increases  in  efficiency  at  exactly  the 
same  rate  as  the  market  wage.  Heckman  has  dubbed  this  case  "Michael- 
neutrality".   For  0<a<l,  efficiency  still  increases  with  human 
capital  accumulation,  but  the  increase  is  not  as  fast  as  the  increase 
in  market  efficiency,  so  the  opportunity  cost  of  leisure  increases 
with  investment.   For  a>l,  the  increase  in  the  efficiency  of  leisure 
time  is  greater  than  that  in  work  time,  so  the  opportunity  cost  of 
leisure  actually  falls  with  investment  in  human  capital.  We  want  to 
investigate  how  this  leisure-technology  parameter  influences  the 
optimal  profile  of  human  capital  accumulation. 

The  formal  choice-problem  for  the  individual  is  to  select  a 
life  cycle  profile  for  consumption  of  goods  and  leisure  and  invest- 
ment in  human  capital  to  maximize  the  lifetime  utility  function  in 
(12)  subject  to  the  lifetime  budget  constraint  and  production  func- 
tion for  human  capital.   The  formal  solution  to  this  problem  appears 
in  Appendix  B.  As  before,  our  interest  focuses  upon  the  two  first- 
order  conditions  for  investment  time: 

(1  -  £^  +  a£*)  ^|-  =  (l+OR,  (13) 

.  ,      *  *   dF  *      *   dF  2_ 

(1-Hr)(l  -  l2  -   K2  +  a£2)  ||-  +  (1  -  ^  +  a^)  ^-   =  (1+r)^     (14) 


-15- 

* 

where  £.  again  means  that  leisure  is  being  chosen  optimally. 

These  equations  differ  from  the  marginal  conditions  In  the  pre- 
vious section  by  the  addition  of  one  (or  more)  extra  term  of  benefits 

*  dF 
on  the  left  hand  side.   For  example,  a£_  ~r—~   in  (13)  represents  the  con- 

.5  dK„ 

sumption  benefits  received  in  period  three  (in  terms  of  increased 
efficiency  of  leisure  time)  from  investing  in  human  capital  during 
period  two.   Ceteris  paribus,  the  presence  of  nonmarket  benefits  in- 
creases the  lifetime  production  of  human  capital. 

Two  interesting  cases  should  be  noted.  When  a=0,  (13)  and  (14) 
reduce  to  the  marginal  conditions  of  the  previous  section,  as  should 
be  expected.   Perhaps  less  expected,  when  a=l,  (13)  and  (14)  reduce 
to  the  marginal  conditions  of  the  wealth-maximization  model.  In  this 
case  planned  lifetime  consumption  of  leisure  disappears  from  the 
calculation  of  marginal  benefits  of  Investment,  because  even  in 
leisure  the  individual  captures  the  returns  from  human  capital 
investment. 

Again  we  want  to  examine  the  life  cycle  profile  of  investment 
time  that  emerges  from  this  model.  The  following  theorem  summarizes 
the  influence  of  the  leisure  technology  parameter  on  the  investment 
profile: 

Theorem  Three:  K.  >  K„  is  the  only  feasible  investment  profile 
that  satisfied  (13)  and  (14)  when 
(a)  a=l 
or  (b)  0  <  a  <  1  and  I*  >_  SL* 

*     * 

or  (c)  a>l  and  £-  _<  &„ 


-16- 


Proof :  We  proceed  with  a  proof  by  contradiction.   Suppose  K=K  =K, 

AV  AV  ATI  AT? 

so  — — -  ■  t— -  =  —  .  Combining  (13)  and  (14)  to  eliminate  -r=i 

diC.         or.,,        aK  QK. 


'2 


^(1-£2-K2  +  aV _     1.      ^ 


<i+r>    (i  -  %  ;,i3)    hi  +  (i+r)Hi =  (i+r)^0      <i5> 

Differentiation  of  the  left  hand  side  of  (15)  with  respect 

to  K  shows  it  is  a  nondecreasing  function  of  K  since 

(1+r)2  (1  -  £„  -  K  +  a£  )  3H- 

■  >  0  . 


(1  -  £3  +  a£3)      9K 


Now  evaluate  the  left  hand  side  of  (15)  at  K=0,  where  the  expression 

attains  its  smallest  value: 

(1  +  (a-l)£  ) 
(1+r)  H0  (1  -f  (a-l)£3)  +  ^"o  (16) 

It  is  evident  that  the  value  of  (16)  varies  both  with  the  value 
of  a^  and  relation  between  £_  and  £.. 

Suppose  a=l,  as  in  part  (a)  of  the  theorem.   (15)  reduces  to 

1 

(l+r)2H0  +  (l+r)H0  =  (l+r)2HQ 

which  cannot  hold  with  equality.  And  since  the  left  hand  side  of  (15) 
only  increases  as  K  increases,  the  assumption  K=K„  always  produces 
a  contradiction.  Following  the  previous  two  proofs,  the  assumption 
1C  >  K2  only  serves  to  make  matters  worse,  so  KL.  >  K»  is  the  only 
possible  assumption  that  does  not  produce  a  contradiction. 

Now  as  in  part  (b)  of  the  theorem,  suppose  0<a<l.  For  K=0  and  £_ 
sufficiently  less  than  £„,  the.  first  term  of  (16)  can  be  made  arbitrarily 
small,  so  (15)  can  possibly  hold  with  equality.   However,  for  £,  _>  £_ 


-17- 

equality  would  be  again  impossible,  and  only  worse  for  K  >  0  or  1L  >  L. 
Thus  l~   >  L  is  a  sufficient  condition  for  K_  >  K„  given  0  <_  a  <  1. 

As  in  part  (c)  of  the  theorem,  suppose  a>l.   For  Kc0  and  £.„  suffi- 
ciently less  than  £_,  the  first  term  of  (16)  can  be  made  arbitrarily 
small,  so  (15)  can  hold  with  equality.  However,  for  Z„  <^  £_,  equality 
is  again  impossible,  and  only  worse  for  K  >  0  or  K2  >  K..  Thus  l~  £  £- 
is  a  sufficient  condition  for  K.  >  K2  given  a>l.  Q.E.D. 

The  importance  of  Theorem  Three  is  that  it  demonstrates  that  the 
"normal"  declining  investment  time  profile  is  not  the  only  possible 
life  cycle  pattern  to  emerge  when  individuals  behave  as  utility  maximizers 
and  human  capital  provides  consumption  benefits.  When  these  consumption 
benefits  are  small  (0<a<l) ,  so  that  human  capital  augments  the  efficiency 
of  work  more  than  leisure  time,  then  a  sufficient  condition  for  the 
"normal"  declining  investment  time  profile  to  be  optimal  is  that 
leisure  time  is  nondecreasing.  The  intuition  for  the  possibility  of  an 
"abnormal"  increasing  profile  of  investment  time  is  similar  to  that 
for  Theorem  Two.   Since  most  returns  to  investment  in  human  capital 
(but  not  all  returns,  if  a>0)  are  enjoyed  only  when  the  individual 
is  working,  if  work  time  is  most  intensive  late  in  life  and  if  the 
future  is  heavily  discounted,  then  later  rather  than  earlier  investment 
may  be  more  profitable.  A  similar  (but  reversed)  argument  follows 
when  a>l.  Now,  human  capital  augments  the  efficiency  of  leisure 
time  more  than  work  time.   Since  most  returns  to  human  capital  now 
accrue  during  leisure  time,  if  leisure  time  is  increasing  over  the 
life  cycle,  the  incentives  to  invest  in  human  capital  might  increase 
with  age  if  the  future  is  sufficiently  discounted. 


-18- 

The  most  interesting  result  is  that  if  human  capital  is  "neutral," 
so  that  investment  in  human  capital  equally  augments  the  efficiency 
of  work  and  leisure,  then  the  "normal"  declining  investment  time  profile 
is  the  only  feasible  pattern.  And  since  (13),  (14)  and  (15)  are  all 
monotonic  in  ji,  we  can  say  that  the  closer  human  capital  is  to  being 
neutral,  the  more  likely  a  normal  investment  profile  emerges  regardless 
of  the  life  cycle  of  leisure.  Again,  the  intuition  should  be  clear. 
For  a=l,  the  first-order  conditions  are  formally  the  same  as  in  the 
wealth  maximization  model  where  the  "normal"  investment  profile  was 
the  only  feasible  pattern.   Since  human  capital  is  neutral,  the  alloca- 
tion of  time  between  work  and  leisure  activities  over  the  life  cycle 
does  not  affect  the  returns  from  investing  in  human  capital  so  it  cannot 
affect  the  timing  of  such  investment  over  the  life  cycle. 

Theorem  Three  assumes  that  leisure  time  is  always  being  chosen 
optimally  to  satisfy  the  system  of  first  order  conditions  in  Appendix 
B.  What  does  this  life  cycle  of  leisure  look  like?  Just  as  in  Section 
IV,  very  little  can  be  said  without  imposing  additional  structure  to 
the  utility  function.   If  we  once  again  assume  separability  of  time  and 
goods  within  each  period  and  if  we  assume  that  the  utility  function  differs 
across  time  only  by  the  individual's  subjective  rate  of  discount,  then 

we  can  write 

* 
dz 


d£  ILa   H 
dz     a2 


d£3H2a 


* 
where  z  is  the  utility  operator  on  leisure  time. 


-19- 

Notice  that  this  condition  is  not  quite  identical  to  equation  (11) 

in  Section  IV  because  of  the  presence  of  efficiency  effects  on  leisure. 

*  a 

If  we  assume  that  z  is  homogeneous  of  degree  e  in  H,  ,  then 


* 
dz 

2 

«T 

* 

dz 

d£2Hl 

d*2 

(17) 

can  be  : 

rewritten  as 

* 
dz 

d£2 

* 
dz 

H^a£ 

dJS 

t. 

(18) 


Equation  (18)  suggests  that  the  life  cycle  of  leisure  depends  in 
part  upon  the  leisure  technology  parameter  a_.   Suppose  a^  is  sufficiently 
small  so  that  1  -  ae  >  0.  Since  EL  >_  EL,  then  l~   <_  £„  or  in  other 
words,  leisure  time  declines  over  the  life  cycle.  But  according  to  part 
(b)  of  Theorem  Three,  these  are  the  exact  conditions  under  which  the 
optimality  of  the  "abnormal"  increasing  profile  of  investment  time  can 
not  be  ruled  out.  Now  suppose  a_  exceeds  one  by  a  sufficient  amount  so 
that  1  -  ae  <  0.  For  EL,  >L,  H*""**  £  H^"ae  and  *3  >_  *2;  or  in 
other  words,  leisure  time  increases  over  the  life  cycle.  According  to 
part  (c)  of  Theorem  Three,  these  conditions  also  are  consistent  with 
the  possible  optimality  of  the  "abnormal"  increasing  investment  profile. 

To  summarize,  our  investigation  of  the  life  cycle  of  leisure  permits 
many  feasible  paths  for  leisure  time  over  the  life  cycle.  It  is  not 
possible  to  show  that  the  only  optimal  paths  for  leisure  coincide  with 
the  sufficient  conditions  stated  in  Theorem  Three  for  the  optimality  of 
the  "normal"  declining  investment  profile.  The  leisure  profile  can 
reasonably  follow  paths  that  might  be  consistent  with  nondecreasing  in- 
vestment time. 


-20- 

VI   Summary  and  Extensions 

This  paper  offers  sufficient  conditions  (in  terms  of  three  theorems) 
under  which  the  optimal  amount  of  time  devoted  to  human  capital  produc- 
tion declines  over  the  life  cycle.  The  results  have  been  stated  in 
this  form  since  there  is  some  casual  empirical  evidence  that  a  declining 
profile  is  the  "normal"  life  cycle — particularly  when  human  capital 
production  take  the  form  of  schooling.  To  summarize  these  conditions, 
a  declining  investment  profile  is  the  only  feasible  path  if 

1.  Individuals  maximize  lifetime  income,  or 

2.  Individuals  maximize  lifetime  utility  and  human  capital  is 
"neutral"  in  its  effects  on  the  efficiency  of  work  and  leisure 
time  (a=l),  or 

3.  Individuals  maximize  lifetime  utility,  human  capital  is 
"biased"  towards  market  efficiency  (0  <^ a  <  1),  and  leisure  time 
increases  over  the  life  cycle,  or 

4.  Individuals  maximize  lifetime  utility,  human  capital  is 
"biased"  towards  leisure  efficiency  (a  >  1),  and  leisure  time 
decreases  over  the  life  cycle. 

If  none  of  these  conditions  is  satisfied,  then  other  investment  profiles 
may  be  possible,  including  increasing  investment  time  over  the  life  cycle. 
How  likely  is  it  that  one  of  these  four  conditions  will  be  satisfied? 
The  recent  human  capital  literature  dismisses  the  first  possibility  of 
wealth  maximization  as  an  unrealistic  paradigm.   If  individuals  behave 
as  utility  maximizers,  then  the  question  reduces  to  an  examination  of 
the  neutrality  or  nonneutrality  of  human  capital  (the  value  of  a). 
Unfortunately  there  have  been  very  few  attempts  at  estimating  the  value 


-21- 

9 
of  the  leisure  technology  parameter  a_.    If  It  could  be  demonstrated, 

for  example,  that  human  capital  was  approximately  neutral,  then  there 
would  be  evidence  that  the  second  condition  is  satisfied.  This  is 
obviously  a  question  that  cannot  be  resolved  without  a  good  deal  more 
evidence. 

There  is  another  way  in  which  the  current  work  is  unsatisfactory. 
Our  treatment  of  nonmarket  benefits  of  human  capital  in  Section  V  is 
really  assymmetric.   If  an  increase  in  the  stock  of  human  capital  makes 
both  work  and  leisure  time  more  efficient,  then  why  doesn't  it  also 
raise  the  efficiency  of  the  other  use  of  time — investment  time?  The 
production  function  could  and  should  be  amended  to  include  the  possi- 
bility of  neutral  or  nonneutral  increases  in  the  efficiency  of  invest- 
ment time.  One  could  rewrite  equation  (1)  as 

Hi  ~  Hi_i  =  F(KiHi_i>  <19> 

where  b  is  a  positive  learning  technology  parameter.   If  b=l,  equation 
(19)  suggests  that  part  of  the  current  stock  of  human  capital  Is  itself 
an  input  in  the  production  of  additional  human  capital.  This  neutral 
specification  was  introduced  by  Ben-Porath.   If  0  <  b  <  1,  acquisition 
of  human  capital  still  augments  the  production  of  future  human  capital 
but  not  as  much  as  it  increases  market  earnings — human  capital  is 
biased  toward  work.  For  b  >  1,  human  capital  is  biased  toward  invest- 
ment since  the  efficiency  of  investment  time  rises  faster  than  market 
wages . 

Just  as  we  investigated  the  effect  of  the  leisure  technology  para- 
meter a_  on  the  life  cycle  profile  of  investment,  so  too  could  we,  in 


-22- 

principle,  investigate  the  effect  of  the  learning  technology  parameter 
b_.  Unfortunately,  this  does  not  turn  out  to  be  a  very  easy  task.   It 
is  impossible  to  offer  any  closed  form  conditions  that  summarize  the 
influence  of  b_  on  the  investment  profile.   It  is  easy  to  see  why  this 
is  so:   raising  b_  has  two  opposing  effects.  On  the  one  hand,  raising 
b_  Increases  the  incentives  to  invest  now  because  it  raises  the  marginal 
benefit  of  current  human  capital  production  since  returns  will  accrue 
not  only  as  higher  future  earnings,  but  also  as  lower  costs  of  future 
production.   On  the  other  hand,  raising  b_  increases  the  incentives  to 
postpone  some  investment  since  future  marginal  costs  will  be  lower. 
While  it  may  not  be  possible  to  explicitly  derive  any  theorems 
on  the  effect  of  b_  on  the  investment  profile,  Paula  Stephan  has  in- 
vestigated the  influence  of  _b  through  computer  simulation  analysis. 
She  shows  how  life  cycle  investment  and  earnings  profiles  will  be 
affected  when  human  capital  has  a  market  bias  (0  <_ b  <  1)  and  when  it  has 
a  production  bias  (b  >  1) .  Unfortunately,  however,  she  assumes  that 
the  individual  selects  his  investment  plan  to  maximize  lifetime  income, 
not  lifetime  utility.   It  would  be  interesting  to  investigate  how 
Stephen's  conclusions  are  affected  by  a  change  in  the  objective  function. 
This  paper  suggests  her  results  may  well  be  very  sensitive  to  the  wealth 
maximization  criterion.  As  yet,  the  question  remains  unresolved. 


M/D/190 


1See  Blaug  [3]. 


-23- 
Footnotes 


2 
Five  articles  are  noteworthy.   They  are  Blinder  and  Weiss  [4],  Ryder, 

Stafford  and  Stephen  [10],  Ghez  and  Becker  [5],  and  two  by  Heckman  [7,8]. 

3 

For  example,  Becker  [1]  and  Ben-Porath  [2]. 

4 
Of  course,  even  firms  can  be  constrained  in  the  presence  of  internal  or 

external  adjustment  costs.  Blinder  and  Weiss  point  out  the  formal  simi- 
larity between  a  firm's  investment  behavior  faced  with  adjustment  costs 
and  human  capital  accumulation. 

Ryder,  Stafford,  and  Stephen  [10],  page. 

2 
6  dF      d  F 

Specifically,  it  is  assumed  that  —  >  0,  — =■  <  0,  F(0)  =  0, 

AK 
Um  dF  ,n.        .  Aim  dF  ...        n 

*K>  d£  (0)  ~   "•  and  E4  dK  (1)  =  °' 

7 See  Michael  [9]. 

g 
See  Heckman  [7]. 

9 
Graham  [6]  cannot  reject  the  hypothesis  that  a=l  based  upon  a  panel 

study  of  the  human  capital  investment  behavior  of  some  900  families 

surveyed  by  the  Michigan  Survey  Research  Center. 

10See  Stephen  [11], 


-24- 


Appendix  A 


The  individual  selects  X  ,  X.,  X  ,  £  ,  £_,  £  ,  IL,  and  K~  to 
maximize 


uCXj^,^)  +  v(X2,£2)  +  z(X3,£3) 


subject   to   the  budget  constraint 


(l+r)2(l-£1-K1)wH0  +  (l-H:)(l-£2-K2)wH1 


+  (l-£3)wH2  -   (1+r)^  -   (l+r)X2  -  X3  =*  0 


and  the  human  capital  production  functions 


H2  =  Hx  +  FCi^) 

The  first-order  necessary  conditions  (where  X  is   the  multiplier  associated 
with   the  budget  constraint)   are: 

Su/SXj^  -  X(l-Hr)2  =  0  (A.l) 

3v/9X2  -  X(l+r)   =   0  (A. 2) 

3z/8X3   -  A  =   0  (A. 3) 

3u/3£1   -   X(l+r)2wHQ   =  0  (A.4) 

3v/3£2   -   X(l+r)wH1  =   0  (A.5) 

3u/3£3   -  XwH2  =   0  (A. 6) 

d+r)  a-vVoTr +  (1-V^k~  =  (1+r>2H0     (A-7) 


-25- 


(i-v§ 


U+OHj, 


(A.8) 


(14r)Z(l-£1-K1)wH0  +  (1-hr)  (l-£2-K2)wH1 
+  (l-£3)wH2  -   (1+r)^  -   (l+r)X2  -  X3  =  0 


(A.9) 


-26- 


Appendix  B 


The  individual  selects  X  ,  X.,  X  ,  £.,  I   ,  9. '  ,  iL,  and  K  to 
maximize 


u(X1,£1H0a)  +  v(X2,Jl2H1a)  +  z(X3,£3H2a),          a>0 

subject  to   the  budget  constraint  and   production  functions   in  Appendix  A. 
The  first  order  conditions  are: 

Su/SXj^   -  A(l-fx)2  -  0  (B.l) 

3v/3X2   -  A(l+r)   -  0  (B.2) 

3z/3X3  -  A  =  0  (B.3) 

H*  -  A(l+r)2wHn  =  0  (B.4) 


— — — H  a  -  A(l+r)wH1    =   0  (B.5) 

— — —  H  a  -  AwH„  =   0  (B.6) 

3SH2a 


3v          .   ua-l  dF      ,        3z  .   ..a-1  dF 
a£„Hn        -rr—  +  a£_H0        -y=- 

3*2^        2  1        dh        3£3H2a        3   2        dKl 


+  K-Cl+r)2^  +   (1-h:)  (l-Aj-K^wg- 


+  d-^3)v^|-  )   =  0  (B.7) 


-27- 


a^X"1  ~-  +  XC-U+OwH- 


a*3H2a        3   2       dK2  1 

+   d-A3)«^)    "  °  (B.8) 


(l+r)2(l-£1-KL)wH0  +   (l+r)(l-il2-K2)wH1 

+  (l-Z3)wH2  -   (1+r)^   -   (l+r)X2  -  X3  -  0  (B.9) 

To  obtain  equation     (13)    in  the  text,    substitute   (B.5)   and    (B.6) 
into   (B.7).      To  obtain  equation   (1A)    in  the   text,    substitute   (B.6)    intc 
(B.8). 


-28- 


References  Cited 


[1]  Becker,  Gary,  Human  Capital,  New  York:   NBER,  1975. 

[2]  Ben-Porath,  Yoram,  "The  Production  of  Human  Capital  and  the  Life 
Cycle  of  Earnings,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy  (August  1967). 

[3]  Blaug,  Mark,  "Human  Capital  Theory:   A  Slightly  Jaundiced  Survey," 
Journal  of  Economic  Literature  (September  1976). 

[4]   Blinder,  Alan  and  Ycram  Weiss,  "Human  Capital  and  Labor  Supply: 
A  Synthesis,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy  (June  1976). 

[5]   Ghez,  Gilbert  and  Gary  Becker,  The  Allocation  of  Time  and  Goods 
Over  the  Life  Cycle,  New  York:   NBER,  1976. 

[6]   Graham,  John,  "The  Influence  of  Nonhuman  Wealth  on  the  Accumula- 
tion of  Human  Capital,"  manuscript. 

[7]  Heckman,  James,  "A  Life  Cycle  Model  of  Earnings,  Learning,  and 

Consumption,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy  (August  1976,  part  2). 

[8]  Heckman,  James,  "Estimates  of  a  Human  Capital  Production  Function 
Embedded  in  a  Life  Cycle  Model  of  Labor  Supply,"  in  Nestor 
Terleckyj,  editor,  Household  Production  and  Consumption,  New  York: 
NBER,  1976. 

[9]   Michael,  Robert,  The  Effect  of  Education  and  Efficiency  in  Con- 
sumption, New  York:   NBER,  1972. 

10]   Ryder,  Harl,  Frank  Stafford  and  Paula  Stephen,  "Training  and 
Leisure  over  the  Life  Cycle,"  International  Economic  Review 
(October  1976). 

11]  Stephen,  Paula,  "Human  Capital  Production:  Life-Cycle  Production 
with  Different  Learning  Technologies,"  Economic  Inquiry  (December 
1976).