Skip to main content

Full text of "Optimal plant size and industrial structure before the modern industrial corporation"

See other formats


"€#* 


Y?^\  t     J~~5 


\m 


CENTRAL  CIRCULATION  BOOKSTACKS 

The  person  charging  this  material  is  re- 
sponsible for  its  renewal  or  its  return  to 
the  library  from  which  it  was  borrowed 
on  or  before  the  Latest  Date  stamped 
below.  You  may  be  charged  a  minimum 
fee  of  $75.00  for  each  lost  book. 

Theft,  mutilation,  and  underlining  of  book*  are  reason* 
for  disciplinary  action  and  may  result  In  dismissal  from 
the  University. 

TO  RENEW  CALL  TELEPHONE  CENTER,  333-8400 
UNIVERSITY   OF    ILLINOIS    LIBRARY   AT   URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 


HAY  o. 

APR  15 


When  renewing  by  phone,  write  new  due  date  below 
previous  due  date.  L162 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/optimalplantsize935jere 


FACULTY  WORKING 
PAPER  NO.  935 


«P: 


Optimal  Plant  Size  and  Industrial  Structure 
Before  the  Modern  Industrial  Corporation 


r" 

* 

c 

•J? 

03 

50 

73 

t 

39 

-< 

0 

-^ 

1 

m 

Jeremy  .Mack 


College  of  Commerce  and  Sussnes-s  Administration 
Bureau  of  Economic  and  Business  Research 
University  of  Illinois,  Urbana-Champaicn 


BEBR 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPER  NO.  935 
College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 
February  1983 


Optimal  Plant  Size  and  Industrial  Structure 
Before  the  Modern  Industrial  Corporation 


Jeremy  Atack,  Associate  Professor 
Department  of  Economics 


Not  to  be  quoted  or  cited  without  the  permission  of  the  author. 


Abstract 
The  transition  from  small,  seasonal  businesses  meeting  local  needs 
to  the  large  scale  corporation  serving  a  national  market  in  America  took. 
less  than  a  hundred  years  from  1840  to  1920.   Alfred  Chandler  explains 
the  change  as  a  response  to  high-speed,  continuous  production  processes 
and  mass  distribution  (especially  from  1880  onward)  and  the  interaction 
between  these  two  factors.   This  paper  emphasizes  the  crucial  role 
played  by  external  economies  of  scale  in  the  transition  since  production 
economies  in  many  processes  were  rapidly  exhausted.   At  the  same  time, 
the  changes  for  many  firms  at  this  time  stemmed  from  taking  advantage  of 
the  factory  system  and  more  completely  exploiting  the  production 
economies  available  from  pre-Civil  War  techologies,  post-1880,  rather 
than  from  the  adoption  of  the  revolutionary  mass  production  methods  then 
being  pioneered. 


Optimal  Plant  Size  and  Industrial  Structure 
before  the  Modern  Industrial  Corporation* 


According  to  Alfred  D.  Chandler,  Jr.  (1977,  esp.  pp.  287-314),  the 
modern  industrial  corporation  evolved  from  the  technological  imperati- 
ves of  the  late  nineteenth  and  early  twentieth  centuries.   High-speed, 
continuous  production  processes  and  the  ever-expanding  markets  needed 
to  absorb  their  output  demanded  new  and  specialized  management  forms 
to  oversee  their  operation.   The  small  scale,  individually  owned  and 
managed  manufactory  became  economically  obsolete  and  was  replaced  by 
the  large  scale,  investor-owned  and  professionally-managed  factory. 
The  transition  from  the  small,  seasonal  business,  meeting  local 
needs,  to  the  large  corporation  serving  a  national  market  year-round 
took  less  than  a  hundred  years,  from  1840  to  1920  (Chandler,  1977). 

This  paper  examines  the  extent  and  universality  of  this  change  by 
determining  what  scale  of  plant  survived  during  the  early  stages  of 
the  transition  and  the  implications  that  this  had  for  the  industrial 
structure  in  the  latter  half  of  the  nineteenth  century.   In  most 
industries,  production  economies  were  rapidly  exhausted,  but  plants 
continued  to  benefit  from  mass  distribution  and  it  was  the  conjunction 
of  mass  production  with  mass  distribution  by  a  few  firms  that 
increased  concentration  and  radically  altered  industrial  structure. 
Nevertheless  these  changes  were  limited  to  relatively  few  firms  and 
the  small  firm  continued  to  survive  and  remained  the  typical  producing 
unit  in  spite  of  these  changes.   Indeed,  these  changes  may  have  even 
added  to  small  firm  vigor.   Specifically,  I  will  determine  what  size 
of  plant  survived  during  the  period  1850-1870  before  most  of  the  new 
technologies  were  innovated  and  how  many  of  these  plants  would  have 


-2- 

been  needed  to  satisfy  demand  with  no  changes  in  technology  or  the 
extent  of  the  market  during  the  subsequent  period. 

I.   Constraints  on  Factory  Production 

Faced  by  scarce  labor  and  capital,  limited  power  resources,  and 
poor  transport  facilities,  most  manufacturing  firms  in  the  first  half 
of  the  nineteenth  century  remained  small  (Bateman  and  Weiss,  1975  and 
1981).   The  wage  labor  supply  was  small  in  a  country  with  few  large 
urban  areas  (Williamson  and  Swanson) ,  and  ample  opportunities  to  set  up 
as  a  yeoman  farmer  (Danhof,  1941).   Large  firms  had  to  resort  to 
various  devices  to  create  a  captive  labor  force.   The  New  England  tex- 
tile mills,  for  example,  tapped  the  pool  of  unmarried  farm  girls  by 
offering  a  supplementary  source  of  income  to  the  impoverished  farm  sec- 
tor and  education  and  strict  moral  guidance  to  their  employees 
(Abbott,  1908-1909).   In  the  South,  slaves  were  often  used,  especially 
in  the  iron  "plantations"  (Bradford,  1959),  or  else  manufacturers  such 
as  William  Gregg  or  Daniel  Pratt  resorted  to  building  model  com- 
munities to  tie  labor  to  the  mill  (Mitchell,  1928;  Miller,  1972). 
Capitalization,  too,  remained  small  so  long  as  the  investor's  liabi- 
lity was  unlimited.    Businesses  had  to  rely  upon  the  personal  resour- 
ces of  the  owners,  their  relatives,  and  friends  and  the  good  offices 

2 
of  their  suppliers  for  investment  funds.    It  also  meant  that 

investors  were  unwilling  to  relinquish  day-to-day  supervision  to  pro- 
fessional managers,  preventing  the  division  of  labor  within  firms  and 
the  division  of  talent  between  firms.   Where  power  was  needed,  it  was 
usually  water.   Yet  the  power  capabilities  of  most  water  rights  were 
quite  small  and  usually  seasonal;  unusable  in  the  winter's  Ice  or 


-3- 

summer's  drought  and  flooded  out  in  the  freshets  of  spring.   Even 
along  the  Fall  line  where  quite  large  water  powers  were  available  and 
which  were  less  plagued  by  seasonality,  the  demands  for  more  power 
from  growing  firms  exhausted  the  hydraulic  potential  of  the  site 
(Atack,  Bateraan  and  Weiss,  1980).   Poor  transport  facilities  com- 
pounded the  problems  of  seasonality  and  more  importantly,  the  high 
cost  of  transportation  limited  the  distance  over  which  goods  could 
profitably  be  shipped  to  market. 

Machines,  particularly  cheaply  built  machines,  could  be  substituted 
for  some  of  the  scarce  labor,  but  so  long  as  work  was  seasonal  and  the 
geographic  boundaries  of  the  market  were  limited,  there  was  little 
incentive  to  adopt  the  technology,  improve  it  or  adapt  it  to  new  appli- 
cations.  Although  Oliver  Evans'  highly  mechanized,  continuous  process 
flour  mill  was  widely  adopted  by  the  industry,  its  principles  were  not 
applied  to  other  activities  during  the  antebellum  period  (Chandler, 
1977).   Similarly,  although  the  New  England  textile  mills  had 
pioneered  the  integrated  factory  system,  there  were  few  imitators 
until  just  before  the  Civil  War  when  the  sewing  machine  began  to  be 
adopted  by  the  boot  and  shoe  industry  (Ware,  1931;  Hazard,  1921). 

From  1840  onward  these  constraints  were  progressively  eased  by  the 
railroad  and  the  substitution  of  steam  for  water  power.   The  spreading 
railroad  network  significantly  reduced  the  costs  of  distribution  and 
banished  the  seasonal  dependency  of  other  transportation  media.   By 
I860  the  east  coast  and  midwest  had  a  basic,  albeit  not  fully  inte- 
grated, network  but  which  did  include  direct  links  between  the  midwest 


-4- 

and  major  eastern  cities,  and,  by  1370,  52,922  miles  of  track  were  in 
use  nationwide  (Poor,  1890). 

The  adoption  of  steam  power,  made  possible  and  economic  by  new  and 

cheaper  supplies  of  coal,  freed  firms  from  the  locational  constraints 

of  waterpower,  its  seasonality  and  the  difficulty  in  expanding  the  power 

3 
available.    Steam-powered  plants  could  be  located  in  towns  and  cities 

4 
rather  than  alongside  the  nearest  feasible  water-right.   Labor  supply 

problems  were  at  once  eased  and  the  urban  environment  not  only  consti- 
tuted a  larger  market  for  manufactured  products,  but  was  also  usually  a 
node  in  the  railroad  network.   Lastly,  the  steam  engine  permitted  the 
use  of  power  intensive  machinery  on  an  extensive  scale  and  the  factory 
system  came  into  being  in  more  and  more  industries. 

II.   Economies  of  Scale  and  Factory  Production 

Factory  production  did  not  necessarily  imply  large  scale  opera- 
tion; the  technology  of  the  day  was  not  one  that  demanded  high  rates 
of  output  to  realize  lowered  production  costs.   Indeed,  what  evidence 
we  have  suggests  that  the  potential  economies  of  scale  were  often 
realizeable  by  relatively  small  plants. 

The  usual  method  of  estimating  production  functions,  ordinary  least 
squares,  disguises  the  rapid  exhaustion  of  scale  economies  as  it  implies 
a  linear  cost  function  and  scale  economies  independent  of  plant  size. 
k   number  of  alternative  production  function  forms  have  been  developed 
which  have  the  property  that  scale  elasticity  varies  with  plant  size. 
Within  certain  parameter  limits,  these  are  consistent  with  a  U-shaped 
long-run  average  cost  curve.   I  do  not,  however,  impose  prior  constraints 
upon  the  parameters. 


-5- 

Consider  Che  following  Cobb-Douglas  version  of  the  Zellner  and 
Revankar  (1969)  function: 

ln(VX)  =  In  A  +  (I  •  In  L  +  g  •  In  (K/L)  [1] 

where:   V  =  value-added 
L  =  labor 
K  =  capital 
and  ln(V  )  =  In  V  +  0V,  a  monotonic  transformation  of  V. 
This  production  function  is  estimated  using  the  Box  and  Cox  (1963) 
non-linear  maximum  likelihood  method. 

Returns  to  scale,  e,  depend  upon  the  parameter,  0,  the  estimate, 
U ,  and  upon  the  level  of  value-added,  V: 

e  =  u/(l  +  0V) 

For  0  >  1,  returns  to  scale  are  decreasing  with  increasing  plant  size 
measured  by  value-added  and,  when  y  >  1  and  0  >  1,  at  low  levels  of 
value-added,  plants  are  subject  to  increasing  returns  to  scale  which 
eventually  give  way  to  a  range  of  approximately  constant  returns 
followed  by  decreasing  returns  to  scale  as  the  value  of  V  increases. 

Production  functions  using  this  non-linear  maximum  likelihood  method 

Q 

were  estimated  for  plant  data  from  the  1870  census  of  manufacturing. 
Analysis  focused  upon  twenty-four  industries  which  in  1870  produced 
over  50  percent  of  all  manufacturing  value-added  and  represented  about 
a  quarter  of  the  identifiable  industries  at  the  time. 

The  production  function  estimates  of  u   and  the  value  of  0  which 
maximized  the  likelihood  function  are  shown  in  Table  1. 


-6- 


Table  1 

Interpretation  of  the  results  was  not,  however,  straightforward.   In 
approximately  a  third  of  the  twenty-four  cases,  the  value  of  0  which 
maximized  the  likelihood  function  was  negative.   This  would  imply 
scale  economies  that  increased  with  plant  size,  a  notion  generally 
contrary  to  our  theory  of  the  firm.   However,  in  none  of  these  instances 
was  the  estimate  of  0  significantly  different  from  zero  suggesting  that 
the  variable  scale  elasticity  production  function  methodology  was  not  a 
significant  improvement  over  fixed  scale  elasticity  forms.   Indeed, 
only  two  estimates  (woolen  mills  and  steam  engine  manufacturer) 

Q 

yielded  values  for  0  that  were  significantly  different  from  zero. 
Although  none  of  the  scale  parameters,  0,  was  estimated  to  be 
significantly  less  than  zero,  negative  values  for  0  should  not  be 
dismissed  as  a  statistical  irregularity.   Other  researchers  using 
different  data  sets  have  encountered  similar  results  but  have  not 
investigated  the  phenomenon  more  closely  (Ringstad,  1974).   The 
problem  appears  to  be  that  not  only  is  the  scale  elasticity  parameter, 
e,  a  function  of  plant  size  but  also  0  itself  is  a  function  of  plant 
size.   A  simple  verification  of  this  can  be  made.   If  the  data  are 
dichotomized  by  plant  size  into  two  mutually  exclusive  groups,  "small" 
and  "large"  plants  in  each  industry,  and  equation  [1]  re-estimated  for 
the  separate  groups,  then  9  is  often  significantly  positive  (and  never 
negative)  for  "small"  plants  and  negative,  often  significantly  so,  for 


—     X 

0    3 

>  c 

1  — 

1        i 

| 

i 

1 

1 

i 

o 

!     1 

1              1              ' 

1 

1 

1 

— . 

_|     15 

US 

ML^. 

C     C 

- 

u|r  |<- 

tf\|in  sc ,  j^  — i  sc 

col 

CK 

lH  jin 

mliri 

pn 

ON 

ccta 

c  -^ 

o! 

— 

11     C 

&: 

CJl©ifM 

CMr"<  -iC  r^pCN 

CJ 

cc 

X  ii 

^Jl^- 

cc 

tr* 

NllTl 

CM 

rsjlrg 

r^ 

u  — 

UM     O 

ClC   NIC   MIO 

a 

C 

r%  ic 

r^-IC 

oio 

it 

C '  ~ 

O    !*) 

c 

C  j  C 

u  ^ 

« 

£!  Jc 

olo  c|c  ola 

c 

C 

CIO 

DC 

O'C 

g" 

ClC 

O    — 

c 

c  c 

n 

C.-C 

B 

!0  '^^ 

_n    — j    j_i 

i 

1 

1  1  1 

1 

'  1  ' 

1 

j\ 

■v<  •— 

1 

1 1 1 

( 

U 

Ll  © 

^—1 

1^    c 

K 

« 

I 

1 

1 

J 

4> 

x 

'      1       ! 

1 

01 

1             1 

J     5) 

>* 

U    ^ 

■S 

M 

J5         -3-1       r-lj 

»A 

IC 

~T 

r*. 

r^t 

-? 

irtl 

— 1 

r^lO 

*0 

u 

ee 

y^ 

U-*  kC    OM>JP    CtCM 

r* 

l/^ 

r^ 

r^ 

C 

rg|f^ 

r*» 

« 

—  r* 

r* 

c 

CO   CC 

<^ 

w 

— 

y 

a 

Oi 

or  ole  — ic 

C 

r^ 

a 

ac 

_ 

pH  lo 

C 

CvC 

™  >, 

n 

to 

^— - 

o    c 

> 

i 

i 

c 

!        1 

j 

I 

1 

u 

i        i 

| 

t 

1 

0      ■ 

] 

| 

i 

[ 

i 

j 

01 

1 

i 

m   > 

1 

1 

■3     0) 

j 

g   — H 

! 

j 

3 

J 

O    u 

00 

X     C 

i          CI 

i 

1 

31 

"i 

i 

U     U 

o 

- 

to 

i 

IT, 

01    u 

™* 

ml 

I 

mi 

1 

B) 

C    01 

oil 

as 

a.  c 

& 

—41 

SI 

| 

3 

— 

-'• 

b 

! 

-* 

in 

e 

u 

3            B0 

cn 

« 

j 

w 

| 

u 

■o 

5 

V 

0,1         0.            3 

e 

~ 

GD 

o 

>i 

U 

3     01 

m 

a 

b                  '          ••* 

o 

' 

1 

V 

2  j 

CC 

H 

JE 

S   .= 

w 

0J 

=1     ""1      = 

•D 

ii 

CJ 

t; 

B 

<J         c         c 

55| 

S 

■ 

Ui 

— 

c 

c! 

u 

s 

—  1       <t        « 

3J 

1 

1 

■^ 

«7 

^t 

-r 

0J     _ 

■B 

>* 

3i       r]       u 

^ 

i 

] 

JJ 

-j 

bS 

- 1 

= 

3    re 

0 

k 

c 

>> 

I 

=  ■ 

3 

BJ 

w 

to 

c 

b 

4-) 

« 

h 

° 

C 

Jg 

aJ 

«! 

C- 

tn 

XI         •*.            Oil 

tl 

ml 

ul 

Sfc 

*" 

(D 

u 

3 

u 

s. 

BO 

— I 

-*' 

■X 

4_t 

£ 

— 

-N        0, 

Ss 

•3 

■o       c 

4-) 

•o 

W 

c 

X 

a 

Hi 

£ 

15     M 

4-1 

c 

o       — 

ra 

o 

•v 

30 

0 

u 

c 

b 

- 

*-l 

^ 

0           b 

«i 

0 

a 

ui 

^ 

h 

x; 

4J 

03 

C 

C     E 

u 

3      - 

_J 

S3 

Ul 

0Q 

C- 

)— t 

LO 

w 

h« 

S 

—     0 

1 

_    i. 

4J 

00 

w     — . 

\ '     " 

•o 

<c 

>> 

1 

J 

3    ii 

pH 

— 

2    c 

u 

o 

*-■ 

ii 

— 1     o 

-^ 

—* 

cr> 

— 

*J 

— • 

.j* 

—        • 

«M 

o 

'-    o; 

r^. 

DO 

-"1     a 

—hi 

r^ 

o> 

un 

— 

rsj 

■<r 

— 

rsi 

c* 

L 

V 

OC 

3 

ir»        >** 

-Hi 

—i 

t*M 

r^ 

m 

<T 

in 

m 

"*. 

01     01 

— 

— 

T 

u 

cmI       cn 

m 

m 

r-i 

(-i 

en 

e»l 

n 

m 

n 

f*» 

^    — 

— 

« 

c 

1 

1                      ' 

W    u. 

u 

<                      1 

c 

to 

c 

1           1           1 

i 

i'  TJ 

— 

Oi 

1  lo 

i 

-C 

' 

a   >.    • 

fQ 

1 

'— 

— 
to 

e 

1 

1     ! 

1           !           i 

1 
1 

j 

_i 

—    u     15 

■O     3     > 

n 

tnt-sl 

Ufr«       CM 

— >           1           ' 

— lu 

3    T    b 

U 

L_. 

■^ 

"i    —■'.    -~H 

<Tlr*i 

-^( 

—— ( 

-ite?i 

ce  — 

<—i— . 

ir> 

r%(oo 

rg 

—    ^    1' 

tC 

u: 

HC     M 

o -=•  M^  i"ila 

o 

g 

ec|r>j 

3  j 

—  !u^ 

O  rsi 

— -, 

■HJO 

cr- 

— 1 

—  jo 

(-1 

—    — 

> 

-J  t-*  1— • 

!N|0    C|iS    -" 

c 

— 

c 

n4  1  O 

r>i! 

ClC 

C    00 

fN 

o  c 

7M 

o 

olo 

5 

™  "■    = 

o 

£l  _!= 

ClC  olo  *» 

c 

C 

c 

O  i  o 

OiC 

OIC 

c  m 

3 

ClC 

C 

c 

olo 

C 

Of 

0;    3 

«-T 

<5 

rat*-' 

III    1  1       I 

1 

1 

1 

1 

1 

1  j 

1 

1 

i 

— 1 

i 

X    t£ 

u 

s° 

—       ««        """ 

~— 

~" 

. 

— 

— 

( 

~ 

3      m      b 

u- 

01 

"" 

1 

1         ' 

i 

3            15 

| 

u     C 

— 

*» 

09 

-2 

*-»]        1(0 

Ifll          OltC      sOKC 

-H 

o 

js 

<o 

r»»  in] 

t^J 

s 

a 

<-k 

X! 

9     3 

Li 

C 

-M        ICT 

Psiltn  cotO  cn j  — 

ohc 

cc 

U-l 

r** 

o 

p^  Ir^- 

« 

<r  |m 

00 

t« 

m  irs. 

C 

u         g 

X' 

4J 

1- 

ui  »|in 

(MJO   Off)   rgjtN 

—* 

cv 

CC 

O 

c 

-h 

— 

0" 

C|C 

C 

"* 

C  jf" 

5°f 

o 

« 

y  u- 

E 

> 

!     i 

1             ' 

1 

1 

I 

w   c   t- 

to 

i     ' 

1 

1 

| 

1 

U                 Cy 

i- 

1    ! 

_J 1 L 

— 1 — 

[.. 

IC     0!     > 

I     I 


=;    ,i 


I 


a- 


3 

° 

_    1 

rl 

cH 

m 

«! 

3 

0.1 

1 

■ 

■~ 

^ 

i 

L.  1 

*3 

u 

3' 

al 

4-1  1 

o 

0 

oil 

M-> 

Oil 

ol 

Zl 

Bui 

i 

ecl 

1 

>, 

1 

1- 

! 

1 

ij     0) 

™\ 

K    - 

Hrtl 

t^| 

mi 

=C| 

3     0 

C ' 

~      "■       c 


01        o 

"I    - 


— '       rsii 


ii   J! 


i      ! 


Q     *J  b             i_ 

b     OS  0 

b     O  " 

oi  s         ra 

0'  — 


T     b   j3 
IJ     o     3 

•J"    U-     ■/ 


it  e  T       " 


-t     - 


T.  — 

6 


COW 

— i 

MM 

— , 

— 

c 

c 

c 

30  cr 

C£ 

5C 

tj 

T      C    — 

V    — 

u: 

0" 

C" 

i-    =  t: 

tr 

^ 

L 

be  s:   s 

w.     K     C 

1     C    £ 

-8- 

9 
large   plants.   The  hypothesis  that  6  was  the  same  for  both  "small" 

and  "large"  plants  in  an  industry  was  almost  always  rejected. 

For  "small"  plants,  scale  elasticity  decreases  rapidly,  so  that 
even  quite  modest  growth  by  "small"  plants  exhausts  the  potential  scale 
economies  available  to  such  firms.   For  "large"  firms  the  puzzle  is  why 
scale  economies  appear  to  increase  for  larger  and  larger  firms.   The 
answer,  I  believe,  lies  in  unidentified  cost  curve  shifts  which  invali- 
date the  results  based  on  the  estimation  of  a  single  production  function. 
The  source  of  such  shifts  may  have  been  technological  discontinuities 
between  "small"  and  "large"  plants. 

Production  function  estimates  assume  technological  homogeneity 
across  the  observations  and  although  the  period  up  to  1870  was  not 
characterized  by  significant  or  rapid  technological  change,  except  for 
the  sewing  machine,  subtle  changes  did  take  place  at  differential  rates 
between  plants  on  the  basis  of  size.   One  important  change,  for  example, 
was  the  adoption  of  steam  power.   Steam-driven  plants,  in  virtually 
every  industry,  were  larger  on  average  than  waterpowered  plants.   For 
example,  steam  driven  saw  mills  produced  an  average  of  $5,400  (1860 
dollars)  value-added  in  1870  compared  with  only  $1,400  for  waterpowered 
mills  and  in  iron  blast  furnaces  and  rolling  mills,  the  averages  were 
$56,700  and  $4,700  respectively  for  steam  and  water  powered  plants. 
These  differentials  were  preserved  in  each  region  including  New 
England  which  had  abundant,  large  waterpower  resources.    The  impor- 
tance of  steam  power  for  the  embodied  technology  in  the  machines  is 


-9- 

not  very  well  documented  but  we  do  know,  for  example,  that  steam- 
powered  spindles  operated  at  higher  speeds  and  produced  a  different 
quality  of  yarn  (Montgomery,  1840,  pp.  69-71).   Similarly,  in  saw  mills, 
the  switch  to  steampower  was  often  accompanied  by  a  switch  to  a  cir- 
cular or  band  saw  with  dramatic  decreases  in  the  kerf  and  sharp 
increases  in  the  throughput  of  lumber  (Reynolds,  1957).   Under  this 
general  heading  of  technological  change  too,  one  can  also  include  the 
transition  from  workshop  to  factory  and  the  organizational  changes 
contingent  upon  that  change.   The  switch  lowered  unit  costs  at  larger 
output  levels  and  factory  production  was  sufficiently  different  and 
distinct  from  workshop/artisan  manufacture  to  warrant  classification 
as  a  separate  technology.   We  cannot,  however,  distinguish  the 
workshop  from  the  factory  using  the  data  in  the  manuscript  censuses. 

A  second  factor  may  also  have  generated  cost  curve  shifts  for  large 
firms,  most  of  which  were  to  be  found  in  New  England  or  the  Middle 
Atlantic  states.   Higher  population  and  transport  densities,  a  more 
skilled  labor  force,  more  sophisticated  capital  markets  and  a  superior 
supply  of  ancilliary  and  support  services  and  products  may  well  have 
placed  the  plants  in  those  areas  on  a  different  family  of  cost  curves 
and  at  the  same  time  have  contributed  to  their  larger  relative  size. 

Within  a  given  technology,  however,  there  is  good  reason  to  suppose 
that  unit  costs  were  lower  for  larger  plants.   The  large  manufacturer 
may  have  been  able  to  exercise  some  monopsony  power  to  purchase  inputs 
at  lower  prices  than  smaller  competitors.   Poor  transport  facilities 
would  have  reinforced  this  power  as  raw  materials  with  a  low  value- 
to-weight  would  not  be  able  to  absorb  the  transport  costs  to  distant 


-10- 

raarkets.  \t    the  same  time,  any  cost  savings  to  large  firms  were 
apparently  passed  along  to  consumers  in  lower  prices  as  the  return  on 
investment  in  large  firms  was  often  less  (but  more  stable)  than  that 
for  small  firms  (Bateman  and  Weiss,  1980).   Large  firms  also  had 
access  to  the  imperfect  captial  market  of  the  time  at  preferential 
rates  (Davis,  1960).   For  very  large  plants,  cost  could  rise  if  only 
from  managerial  difficulties  in  overseeing  such  a  large  operation  and 
controling  costs  with  so  imperfectly  developed  management  tools. 

Although  the  results  in  Table  1  do  not  lend  much  support  for  a 
variable  scale  elasticity  production  function  form  in  preference  to  a 
homogeneous  function,  nevertheless  we  can  use  the  results  from  Table  1 
for  these  industries  for  which  8  >  0  and  u  >  1  to  estimate  the  output 
level  for  which  average  costs  were  a  minimum,  and  the  range  of  outputs 
embraced  by  costs  within  5  and  10  percent  of  the  minimum.   These  can 
then  be  compared  with  the  average  size  of  plant  in  the  industry.   The 
results  are  shown  in  Table  2.   Value-added  has  been  adjusted  using  the 


Table  2 


Warren-Pearson  price  index  to  express  the  results  in  1860  dollars. 
This  step  is  essential  for  the  later  results  as  the  lingering  effects 
of  the  Civil  War  inflation  were  still  apparent  in  the  1870  data  and 
prices  generally  fell  over  the  period  to  the  mid-1390s  (U.S.  Bureau  of 
the  Census,  1975,  Series  E52-63). 

The  relationship  between  decreasing  scale  elasticity  and  the 
average  cost  curve  for  woolen  textiles  is  graphed  in  Figure  1. 

Figure  1 


-11 


-i    =  S  E 

cr    -  X  = 

I  £   -  u  I 

|U   1  i-  •*•! 

oi  =! 

o    E  S.  — 

I  rx  I  r! 


C*J 

— 

c 

-» 

c 

N 

o* 

tn 

r- 

X 

-ff 

(N 

OS 

»-». 

<— 

© 

c 

c 

e 

c 

o 

o 

«M 

~* 

O 

c 

>~s   to 
<  -I 


00C3C033 


01 

u 

e 

2 

c 

o 

o> 

r*. 

£ 

_^ 

<r 

•" 

w 

"" 

■g 

3 

• 

e 

<C 

cr. 

~> 

E 

cr 

CD 

U 

C 

B 

u 

G 

^ 

U 

01 

<s 

H 

SI     <-N 

0) 

a 

—       X 

B 

1 

c 
i-»  — 

C   E 

o 


—  > 


< 

^ 

u 

£ 

B 

p 

— 

4/ 

c 

7 

3 

i~ 

B 

u 

« 

BB 

c 

O 

B. 

^^ 

N 

V. 

Cl 

k« 

i— 

a 

— i 

w 

™ 

^ 

Ifl 

C 

— 

_ 

IB 

01 

— 

a  a  e  a 
o  3  c  o 
ve       a-       c       r< 


5      5      £      o 


»! 


"3 

c 

0 

— 1 

I--1 

< 

e 

01 

01 

~ 

^0- 

3 

i- 

L.  , 

Q 

c 

Ol 

> 

w 

51 

o      o      c 

o      o      o 


-    *   I 


— •  r*  O^ 


m-4  P4  *H 


« 

" 

c 

Q 

o 

o 

c 

c 

c 

o 

C 

o 

c 

o 

o 

o 

c 

c 

Q 

c 

(M 

lT» 

ao 

c 

cr 

c 

o 

c 

(/* 

■ 

— 

rs« 

p-» 

in 

c 

?N 

— * 

^. 

iT> 

_> 

cc 

O 

-r 

CO 

f] 

0)  *£ 

c 

r*. 

JN 

rsi 

5C  IT* 

c 

- 

I 

I 

1 

1 

1 

<-      o      c 
o      o      e 

l     o 


c        c        ^        —        ^ 


r*.  rvl 


=       c       c 

c       3       c 


c       o       c       c       o 


c       c       o 


c;       c       c 


m       in       r*> 


r-  r^  t^ 


r^  i/-  ty\  r>j 


c! 


.=         c-       — 


I    z 


*-  3  - 


tfi  •—  *- 


bJ         ec 


X         tc 

—        a. 


<r        — 


Figure  1 


Economies  of  Scale  and  Index  of  Average  Cost  by  Value-Added  (1860  dollars) 

for  Wool  Textiles  (SIC  2231) 


1.7 


1.6  . 
1.5 


o 
o 


170 


0) 

160 

-a 

c 

M 

JJ 

150 

en 

o 

CJ 

140 

6C 

CO 

O 

no 

> 

< 

120 

no 

100 

e  =  m/(1  +  0V)  =  1.47/(1  +  0.0000059-V) 


1-U   QV  Wii 

AC(V)  =  k(V    -e   )  /M  -  AC(V) 


min 


=  k(V{1/^1}.eQV/lJ)/0. 03731 


10 


15 


I    I 

20   25 


-T— 
30 


t— 
35 


min  AC(V) 


I  $52,576 


40   45   50 


70 


55   60   65 

Value-Added 

(thousands  1860  dollars 


-13- 


Average  costs  are  defined  by: 


AC(V)  «  kCV1"^  •  eQV)l/U 


where  u  and  8  are  from  the  variable  scale  elasticity  production  func- 
tion estimates,  V  is  value-added  and  k  is  a  function  of  input  prices. 
Assuming  competitive  markets  (as  we  must  for  our  production  function 
estimates),  k  is  a  constant. 

In  general,  the  range  of  plant  sizes  with  average  costs  within 
five  or  ten  percent  of  the  minimum  average  costs  is  quite  broad  except 
for  bread  and  other  baked  goods.   In  some  instances,  the  average  cost 
curve  is  very  flat,  as,  for  example,  with  sawmills,  leather  tanning  or 
boots  and  shoes.   A  wide  range  of  plants  of  different  sizes  could  thus 
be  cost  competitive  with  one  another.   Unfortunately,  we  do  not  know 
what  magnitude  of  cost  differences  would  make  firms  non-competitive 
with  one  another.   In  part, this  would  depend  upon  transport  costs  and 
the  firms'  juxtaposition  vis  a  vis  the  transport  network  and  markets; 
it  would  also  depend  upon  the  rate  of  return  each  owner-investor 
demanded  for  the  level  of  risk  being  borne.   Unfortunately,  production 
functions  do  not  address  the  issue  of  the  costs  of  distribution, 
although  Chandler's  (1977)  thesis  that  the  modern  corporation  emerged 
from  the  conjunction  of  mass  production  with  mass  distribution  assigns 
them  a  critical  role. 

A  relatively  narrow  range  for  low  cost  firms  in  the  bakery 
industry  makes  sense.   Product  perishability  and  the  comparatively 
undeveloped  state  of  the  market  for  commercially  baked  goods  would 
limit  the  growth  of  firms  in  the  industry.   The  other  products  were 


-14- 

non-perishable  and  transportable,  though  given  the  ease  of  their  manu- 
facture and  the  sometimes  low  value-to-weight  ratio,  there  was  prob- 
ably little  point  in  producing  more  than  necessary  to  supply  the 
market  in  the  immediate  vicinity.   Nevertheless,  since  not  all  markets 
were  the  same  size  and  scale  economies  remained  more  or  less  constant 
over  a  fairly  wide  range,  the  industries  supported  a  variety  of  dif- 
ferent sizes  of  plant. 

The  average  size  plant  producing  boots  and  shoes,  pig  iron,  sheet 
metal  work,  steam  engines  and  woolen  textiles  was  operating  at  a  scale 
very  close  to  that  which  minimized  average  costs.   Indeed,  I  would 
argue  that  in  only  three  of  the  industries  in  Table  2  were  plants  of 
average  size  producing  at  a  scale  where  costs  were  dramatically  greater 
than  the  minimum:   meat  packing,  distilled  liquers  and  sawmills.   In 
each  case,  the  average  plant  in  the  sample  (and  also  in  the  population) 
was  too  small.   With  comparative  statics  analysis  we  cannot,  however, 
say  anything  about  what  happened  to  these  small  plants  in  the  long-run: 
Some  may  have  grown  and  expanded  into  the  range  of  constant  returns 
becoming  cost  competitive;  some  may  have  been  driven  out  of  business; 
and  others  may  have  continued  to  survive  if  their  (small)  markets  were 
somehow  protected,  as,  for  example,  by  high  transport  costs. 

III.   The  Survivor  Technique 

The  static  nature  of  the  production  function  analysis  and  the 
problems  associated  with  the  estimates  which  we  have  outlined  above 
limit  the  usefulness  of  that  methodology  for  analyzing  changes  in 


-15- 

industrial  structure  and  addressing  the  Chandler  thesis  of  the  con- 
junction of  mass  production  and  mass  distribution  in  the  rise  of  big 
business.   Fortunately,  there  is  an  alternative  means  to  determine 
what  size  of  plant  was  most  efficient  in  1870.   We  can  examine  changes 
in  the  distribution  of  industry  value-added  (in  constant  1860  dollars) 
by  size  of  plant  over  time.   This  approach  is  called  the  "survivor 
technique."  The  survivor  technique  seeks  to  identify  those  size 
classes  of  plant  that  not  only  survived  the  rigors  of  market  competi- 
tion and  the  test  of  time,  but  also  succeeded  in  increasing  their  share 
of  total  industry  value-added  (Stigler,  1958;  Saving,  1961;  Weiss,  1964; 
Shepherd,  1967).   That  is,  it  seeks  to  identify  those  plant  sizes  that 
grew  in  relative  importance  in  an  industry  through  the  long-run  compe- 
titive adjustment  process. 

A  number  of  assumptions  are  implicit  in  the  technique  and  while 
these  have  been  discussed  in  detail  by  others,  notably  by  Shepherd 
(1967),  there  still  appears  to  be  some  confusion  about  them.   Shepherd 
(1967),  for  example,  argues  that  "survivor  estimates  for  firm  sizes 
are  likely  to  be  more  valid  for  atomistic  industries. . .than  for 
highly  concentrated  ones,"  presumably  because  the  assumptions  of 
atomistic  competition  insure  that,  in  the  long-run,  market  pressures 
force  all  plants  to  operate  at  minimum  long-  and  short-run  average  cost 
if  they  are  to  survive.   Profit  maximizing  behavior,  however,  also 
ensures  the  survival  of  lower  cost  plants  even  under  conditions  of 
monopolistic  competition  (Stigler,  1958).   Moreover,  demand  changes 
under  conditions  of  atomistic  competition  affect  only  the  number  of 


-16- 

firras  in  Che  industry  while  such  changes  for  raonopolistically  competi- 
tive industries  will  permanently  alter  the  market  solution,  including 
the  optimum  plant  size.   Similarly,  the  assumptions  of  atomistic  com- 
petition presuppose  no  technological  change  and  yet  the  movement  towards 
a  deterministic  surviving  plant  size  may  be  most  pronounced  when  tech- 
nological charge  is  greatest. 

Under  certain  circumstances,  survivor  technique  results  may  lead 
to  erroneous  conclusions.   Consider,  for  example,  the  problems  posed 
by  the  existence  of  monopoly  elements.   Under  conditions  of  monopo- 
listic competition,  long-run  equilibrium  is  reached  at  some  output  less 
than  that  which  minimizes  long-run  average  cost.   Weiss  (1964)  avoids 
this  problem  by  emphasizing  the  "minimum  efficient"  scale  of  operation 
rather  than  the  range  of  optimal  plant  sizes  emphasized  by  others 
(Stigler,  1958;  Saving,  1961).   However,  if  the  range  of  surviving 
firms  continues  to  be  identified  with  minimum  long-run  average  cost 
then  the  results  will  be  inconsistent  with  production  or  cost  function 
estimates  which  would  show  increasing  returns  to  scale  and  decreasing 
unit  costs.   Similarly,  the  presence  of  externalities  in  distribution 
which  alter  the  cost  minimizing  level  of  output  for  the  product  deli- 
vered to  the  consumer  will  lead  to  inconsistent  results  between  the 
survivor  technique  estimates  which  take  such  factors  into  account  as 
a  matter  of  course  and  those  based  upon  production  functions  which 
focus  purely  upon  the  production  process  internal  to  the  firm. 


-17- 

There  is  no  universal  agreement  on  how  plant  size  should  be 
measured,  yet  alternative  measures  such  as  value-added,  output, 
employment  or  capital  can  lead  to  quite  different  conclusions  during 
periods  of  technological  change.   Consider  a  (Hicks)  neutral  tech- 
nological change  (a  horaothetic  shift  of  isoquants  towards  the  origin) 
in  an  industry  whose  production  function  is  consistent  with  a  U-shaped 
long-run  average  cost  curve.   Such  a  change  leaves  the  shape  of  the 
long-run  average  cost  curve  unchanged,  it  merely  results  in  lower 
costs  at  each  level  of  output.   Under  these  circumstances,  if  plant 
size  were  measured  by  labor  or  capital,  the  survivor  technique  would 
show  smaller  plants  surviving  because  of  the  shift  of  the  isoquants 
towards  the  origin  (A%  less  labor  and  capital  are  needed  to  produce 
the  same  level  of  output),  while  on  an  output  basis,  the  optimal  (or 
minimum  efficient)  plant  size  would  be  unchanged.   If,  instead,  the 
technological  change  had  been  labor-saving,  then  the  apparent  reduc- 
tion in  the  size  of  the  optimal  plant  would  be  greater  if  size  is 
measured  by  employment  rather  than  by  capital  and  vice  versa  if  the 
technological  change  were  capital-saving.    These  scenarios  are  shown 
in  Figure  2.   We  have  elected  to  use  value-added  as  a  measure  of  plant 
size. 


Figure  2 


The  survivor  technique  implications  for  an  optimal  range  of  plant 
sizes  (classified  by  value-added)  over  the  1850,  1860  and  1870  samples 

from  the  manuscript  censuses  of  manufacturers  for  the  24  industries  in 

12 

Table  1  are  shown  in  Table  3.    The  results  generally  reveal  a  wide 


Figure  2 

Effect  of  Neutral,  Labor-Saving,  or  Capital-Saving  Technological  Change  on  Various 

Measures  of  Plant  Size. 


A.  Neutral  Technological  Change: 


Capital 


Ql 

=   Ql' 

OK 

=  OK 

OL 

OL 

KK' 
OK 

-   LL 
OL 

1/  L 


Labor 


B.  Labor-Saving  Technological  Change: 


Capital 


K 
K' 


Ql  =  Ql 

OK   <  OK/ 
OL    OL' 

KK"  <  LL' 

OK    OL 


Labor 


C.  Capital-Saving  Technological  Change: 


Capital 


K 
K' 


Ql  =   *i 

OK   >  OK' 
OL    OL' 

KK'  >  LL' 

OK    OL 


L'   L 


Labor 


-19- 


Table  3 

range  of  optimally-sized  plants  in  almost  every  industry  and  suggest 
that  a  considerable  portion  of  the  long-run  average  cost  curve  may  have 
been  flat.   This  finding  is  consistent  with  the  twentieth  century  cost 
function  studies  reported  in  Walters  (1963),  the  survivor  technique 
results  reported  by  Saving  (1961)  and  production  function  estimates  for 
the  nineteenth  century  (Atack,  1976;  Atack,  1977;  Sokoloff,  1981; 
James,  1982).   There  were  five  industries,  flour-milling,  bread  and 
bakery  products,  tobacco  manufacture,  saw  and  planning  mills,  and  brick 
works,  in  which  the  range  of  surviving  plants  embraced  less  than 
$16,000  value-added.   All  were  locally  produced  and  traded  goods. 
Plants  producing  these  goods  typically  supplied  markets  limited  by  pro- 
duct perishability,  by  localized  brand  loyalties,  or  by  a  low  value-to- 
weight  ratio  in  the  presence  of  high  transport  costs. 

Estimates  of  the  minimum  efficient  scale  of  operation  are  also 
given  in  Table  3.   The  minimum  efficient  scale  of  plant  is  the 
smallest  size  of  plant  which  increased  its  share  of  total  industry 
value-added  over  the  period.   In  industries  suspected  of  not  being 
perfectly  competitive,  this  measure  is  to  be  preferred  to  the  range  of 
optimal  plant  sizes  because  long-run  equilibrium  is  reached  at  some 
output  less  than  that  which  minimizes  long-run  average  cost  (Weiss, 
1964).   The  minimum  efficient  scale  in  many  industries  was  often  quite 


C        I 


10  \r    — 

:  u  i  - 

—  z  —    l.  -j| 
i  it            u  ei  i 

'  >  r  c:    r  ":i 

|  X  o 

e  u  c 

!l-  =  3 

I  IS  "S  U 

i:  c  «i 

!  o-  i  -o 

i  as  i; 

!  I  *" 


51j 

O    lit 

*»  =' 
-i   o! 

-  — 


\C*TO»T*—    C~tN'l^l-^CCI*^.CO,wi*,C^r,-Os'^**-INIi/".   r-~ 

Jpl^iTK^OCC^PO^Ni*C«-?CB"CtC-7 
ffi^nMiM^-fliAn^irNNQONrir-mN^^^rj 


e>   o 

I    =■ 

=  o 


*  >  -o 
ss       o 

u    u    c 


V.  o 

S->00 


n    x 
•  IE" 

r   i'  —  c 

c  tj    a.— 
N<Ob 


CC-l"-f«TNffl«C*N*ffWNff^O*-'rtC*ctr 


lolc 

105   CC 
ITjl"SJ 

hi  ai 

™k 
<i< 

ij  SI 

Up 

5|£ 


X  0»    fa 

C    £«    T5  -^-h-H  (M    —  IN    — «  ~    -*    IN    —    —    *-    —    —    OJ    —    —    — i 


C     V    Ji 
c   JJS 

j 
t 


=-% 

C    C     OC; 

a  — 

c:  kl 

T. 

—   O     10! 

•    U 

0-  V>  — | 

c   to 

n* 

c.  — 

0   —           Ol 

u  — 

a  o   -o 

4' 

■  I 

a    s   a? 

t-t 

-  Tl 

»-   t  ;l 

X 

9! 

C    u    N   Ci 

■c 

© 

a   c—  og ; 

H 

u  so 

BseoiHi 

p-J  i         <T 


cc  cc  so^«  cc        cc  o  o  ee        sc 

co  —  —  —•—>  *    NNHH^^vOrtNOflDrj-r-*    — 
I      I      I      1      [      I      I      1      1      I      )      I      I      I      1      I      I      ' 
—  u-'fMrgfNiccPsi^c-S'^fNrsi 

•       •   C^    ^*  C\i    f"*    mm.    \£>       •  M 

re  —  o 


i    .    . 


z  3     ' 


SO 
X     — 

cc 

M   O 

s  c 

o 


N  —  irNrjlM00N^^inisjNiNj» 
r^      •     •  m  c*         n  n  "4  4     •         e^ 
O  O  -i  O 


o^-c«tno:nn 


- 

— 

0 

— 

— 

P. 

■C 

u 

r 

>. 

9 

L- 

B3 

=." 

0) 

■o 

>^ 

c 

-* 

V 

V 

O 

— 

(8 

L, 

=r 

E9 

14- 

-J 

ts 

T 

Li 

t; 

Gft 

E 

0) 

<J 

«r 

0) 

n 

Z- 

H 

-S 

0! 

(u 

— 

BC 

m 

2: 

00 

e 

l. 

—. 

on 

_ 

■rt 

5 

• 

- 

X 

c 

^r 

V 

JM 

•M 

"B 

r 

ts 

3 

«.' 

p 

i. 

5^ 

U 

— 

C 

C" 

V 

H 

u 

S 

U 

00 

—     BC    «    _rc     ^ 


*H  -O         ^ 


a.  J !  —    -w    C    C   >    B 

U    *B  —     C     2     C  — 

i—    t    i:  -    ;cca*  — 


c    v  — "    u    =    c 


—      T.    —    Jt    — 


—     5£    X      U     U     I-     BC 


|i 


y  a  "el      ■  2  "*  *  *  « 


r-i  rvj  r^j  (*■  rsj  psj 


O     I 


B!  CC    • 

id  r^i 

B  mm    9 
0  m     4 

■c  c  - 

O  O*    •■ 
tC      • 

CC  ^ 


g; 

CD 

— 

— 

B 

*a  c 

-: 

BJ 

m 

ey     • 

X 

rr 

— 

=r 

~  -» 

— 

-z  *o 

— 

H 

— 

t?  «■ 

s 

V 

E 

i 

BC 

F— 

li 

— 

Ci       m 

B 

« 

3  C^ 

— 

> 

X 

Z\ 

-4      ^ 

X 

c 

B   3s 

x 

=^ 

Ci 

^ 

->       p 

i" 

k. 

X 

■j 

ri 

4-     NO 

u 

cr 

— 

s 

C     1 

e 

3 

1" 

r- 

T)  cr 

«^ 

— 

B 

cr 

C 

—  C 

j_ 

— 

T 

>-*  rN 

t 

— 

— 

a  a- 

'— 

(C 

L. 

X  &• 

T 

2 

^; 

1 

a 

c      • 

tt 

5 

c, 

3 

I1  -J 

T 

V 

— 

3 

• 

e  m 

Im 

S* 

X 

-^ 

Ci 

T 

« 

b 

— 

X  c 

^ 

B» 

> 

~ 

ifi 

_    ^ 

V 

X 

^ 

■^ 

1 

E5 

K 

B 

>, 

tP 

rj 

41      - 

mm 

b 

X 

La 

c> 

•i- 

K    sC 

X 

mm 

la! 

ii1 

c. 

T 

X  w> 

«* 

2 

3 

■ 

X 

T 

■c 

X 

£         • 

a* 

i! 

BT 

c 

— 

l-   c 

1 

u 

0  cr> 

•« 

—m 

Cb 

CJ 

—    C?4 

i? 

_ 

X 

u_ 

e 

V. 

3      » 

X 

c 

— 

L- 

E 

•y 

~ 

T 

m 

P    — 

1 

E 

E 

;."" 

"^        1 

C; 

L. 

5 

X 

r»». 

X 

B" 

x  c: 

V 

r 

01 

» 

km 

X 

J3 

• 

1'    BC 

X 

u  v> 

t; 

~ 

k. 

BT 

z 

^ 

»t 

or 

3      - 

(»! 

— 

c 

T 

c 

c 

O 

— 

t^ 

— 

s 

c 

X  c 

t; 

— 

^ 

_> 

l: 

:   c 

u 

IM 

c 

5 

N"        - 

t^: 

CC 

cj 

—    P*. 

E 

s 

JS 

T      1 

mJ 

X 

Cj 

SI 

c 

4» 

C    C    —     X     fib 


3  C^     3  X     ~     Z 

c  -  e  ex 

—  i    e  c  -c  — 

C  3       —  }         m- 


-21- 

13 
small.     In  flour  milling,  for  example,  firms  producing  as  little  as 

S100  (1860  dollars)  value-added  in  1870  could  still  be  efficient.   At 
the  opposite  end  of  the  scale,  the  minimum  efficient  scale  in  cotton 
textiles  was  apparently  $128,000.   Small  textile  mills  could  not  sur- 
vive. 

The  ratio  of  value-added  in  1870  produced  in  optimally  sized 
plants  to  the  value-added  produced  in  those  plants  in  1850  (expressed 
in  constant  1860  dollars)  shown  in  Table  3  is  an  attempt  to  capture 
the  movement  towards  the  concentration  of  value-added  in  optimally 
sized  plants  over  the  period.   In  most  cases,  the  increase  in  the  pro- 
portion of  output  produced  in  optimally  sized  plants  was  quite  large; 
in  17  of  the  24  cases,  there  was  better  than  a  50  percent  increase. 
Moreover,  in  all  but  seven  cases  more  than  half  of  18  70  value-added 
originated  in  optimally  sized  plants.   In  some  cases  the  increase  was 
exceptionally  dramatic.   In  1850,  no  farm  machinery  manufacturer  pro- 
duced more  than  $32,000  value-added,  but  by  1370,  two-thirds  of 
industry  output  was  produced  by  plants  larger  than  that;  among  them 
would  number  firms  such  as  McCormick  ($407,000  (1360  dollars)  value- 
added  in  1870)  and  Case  ($283,000  value-added). 

With  only  two  exceptions  the  range  of  plant  sizes  with  costs 
within  10  percent  of  the  minimum  average  costs  given  in  Table  2 
overlap  the  range  of  optimal  plant  sizes  in  Table  3.   In  some  cases 
the  overlap  was  quite  extensive.   In  the  meat  packing  industry,  the 
range  of  surviving  plants,  532,000-64,000,  compares  favorably  with  the 
range  of  meat  packing  plant  sizes  with  costs  within  10  percent  of  the 
minimum,  314,700-63,600.   In  other  cases,  the  intersection  of  the  two 


-22- 

was  much  less.   In  the  boot  and  shoe  industry,  for  example,  the  ranges 
were  $16,000-256,000  and  $0-49,200  respectively.   The  range  of  sur- 
viving plants  did  not  intersect  with  the  lower  portions  of  the  esti- 
mated average  cost  curve  in  sawmilling  and  in  pig  iron  production. 

In  the  former  case,  surviving  plants  were  "too  small,"  though  even 
today  sawmilling  is  classified  as  a  local  monopoly  protected  by 
transport  costs,  while  in  the  latter  case,  surviving  plants  were  "too 
large."   The  iron  industry  was  one  of  the  few  industries  which  under- 
went rapid  technological  change  between  1850  and  1870  with  hard 
driving,  improved  heat  recovery  in  the  blast  furnace  and  the  introduc- 
tion of  the  Bessemer  process  in  the  1860s.   The  survivor  techniques 

correctly  identifies  integrated  blast  furnaces  and  Bessemer  plants  as 

,  .    14 
surviving. 

Seven  of  the  11  estimates  of  the  size  of  plant  which  minimized 
average  costs  in  Table  2  also  fall  within  the  range  of  optimally  sized 
plants  in  Table  3.   In  two  of  the  "failures,"  distilled  liquors  and 
sawmills,  the  cost  minimizing  plants  in  Table  2  were  larger  than  the 
optimal  range,  while  the  cost  minimizing  plants  in  the  boots  and  shoe 
industry  and  iron  manufacture  were  smaller  than  the  range  of  surviving 
plants. 

From  what  has  been  said  already,  inconsistencies  such  as  these 
between  the  production  function  approach  to  identify  long-run 
equilibrium  plant  size  and  the  survivor  technique  are  to  be  expected. 
On  the  one  hand,  transport  costs  for  a  relatively  homogeneous  product 
which  is  as  easily  and  cheaply  produced  in  one  location  as  another 
would  cause  the  cost  minimizing  plant  to  be  smaller  than  that  based 


-23- 

purely  upoa  production  factors.   On  the  other  hand,  mass  distribution 
lowering  unit  distribution  costs  for  larger  producers  would  cause  the 
cost  minimizing  scale  of  plant  to  be  larger  than  that  determined 
solely  by  production  consideration.   The  survivor  technique  takes  both 
production  and  marketing  distribution  costs  into  account;  production 
function  analysis  doesn't. 

IV.   1870  Optimal  Plants  and  Industrial  Structure  1370-1900 

We  have  used  the  range  of  optimal  plant  sizes  from  Table  3  as  the 
basis  for  estimating  the  number  of  optimal  plants  which  industry  value- 
added  could  have  sustained  with  no  changes  in  technology,  externalities 
or  the  costs  of  transport  between  1870  and  1900.   These  estimates  are 
shown  in  Table  4.   The  figures  indicate  the  number  of  plants  that  would 


Table  4 


have  been  in  the  industry  if  all  plants  had  been  the  same  size  as 
either  the  minimum  efficient  scale  of  plant  in  1870  or  the  largest  sur- 
viving plants  in  1870. 

In  1870  the  number  of  plants  in  more  than  half  of  selected 
industries;  meat  packing,  flour  milling,  bread  and  bakery  products, 
tobacco,  lumber  milling,  millwork,  printing  and  publishing,  saddlery 
and  harness,  brick,  pig  iron,  iron  castings,  and  steam  engine  and 
machinery  industries  fell  within  the  range  defined  by  the  surviving 
plants.   The  distribution  of  plants  could,  therefore,  be  consistent 
with  the  majority  of  plants  having  adjusted  their  scale  of  operation 
into  the  optimal  range.   However,  a  glance  at  Table  3,  which  shows  the 


•—  f«JC>L^'C*S*CCX^C'CNO'"f",»CO 


r  cc  •?  *     •  in  -*j 
*J  \C  N   iC     re   — i   r-> 


—        -t  -i  —  in 


-5"   r-«    fsl    — ■    •—«    t**J    it* 


■O   C 


to  »-. 
—  ee 


re   c 

—   a. 

c   c 


—       c  v. 


< 

C      S! 


I 


o>>"~  —I 

I— 'IOC     CI 

:    i-  oi 


I 


u  a.  I 

iC-| 

e 


"c-t 


C     00 

X    c 

—    18 


o    E 
J  — 

e  u 

=   c 
|s  o 


o    El 


S     OJ 

z  o: 


Si 


■  l.      i 
I-      ! 

.§21 

'-r  e/sj 

|S    l 


^  r- 


X   0">       •  i-   ^      »r*>rsj("**\C      • 
™   i/*1   -X    *■*■•  *j    5   x  PH      ■  — H  i*- * 


— <    IT 


r*.    C 


O*    2  CO  M   ^ 

*■*      •  r*  r*.       -  <£   x 

CC      •  rg  cn  —  m  >c      »nx    ! 

^C-^r^f^-^^tsir^r^-^^.^'-sD    —    — .  -*   —    m    ^c   —  n       •  fsi    -^ 

I       I        I        I        I        I        I        I        I        I        !        I        t        I        1  I        I        '        I        I        I       B      I        I 


^CC 


rs.  —  *ff  rg 


r^O'CXO--m-*p««.C>r-*~ 


o  •**  cm  "H 


iri  Q  rsj 

<—<   cm  <r   C   C 
U>    OC    vO    IT1    C 


"•    X    O    -H  -N  -lAiflNrm^HNNlft 


N     -N     (M    -^  (^    N     c     ^     l^     ^     ©     *D    C1 

hi   N  it .^  •<^r">      «  r*.  f>«»  ©   nc  m 

f^       *C   CO       »0>    N        »CV  f*   <    N       *      •  I/* 
*0<T       "      4NN    O    O        ""-       "      »  CO    *M       • 

03vCHNH("innn^C3aBN«J    CM 

i    i    i    i    i    i    i    I    r    I    !    i    i    i    i 

N.'CO>N*Tt*,ONffi-*e<coo>*,»o 

x  o**  f**  m 


o 

a-,  e 

to 

c  n 

CCl"*- 

*- 

<n  c  X  r> 

-*|X 

c 

in     •     •  u-» 

j*™ 

re 

X   —  -cr    — I 

1 

— - 

» c*  rs)      - 

lu 

0. 

1  e 

1     1     1     1 

] 

pH 

>C  X    O    X 

u 

to 

Nr*0ltt 

at 

B 

•a-  —  cr*  ra 

■a 

E 

•J 

—»  —  <»n 

a 

= 

o 

CM 

<r 

X 

rsl 

» 

• 

■ 

X 

oj 

m 

« 

*s- 

r: 

J 

—t 

cm 

e* 

„ 

" 

cc 

^C 

X 

•vT 

ir 

<NI 

r~ 

— 

j- 

CO  *^^  f^    ^^  CO   ^0    w    C5* 


(OinffvO^N^O^nCODON 

•  r^'CO'^^ccra,>^co>»£ 


CM 


•  ^1    ^   X    "■    O 


©  r**  CO  cr*  m  N  N 

•  eMC*^»r«x\Ct^r*-^\C        -a-i/" 
•  C      *-t     -o*iri     «»«a-     •    -    •  c  ** 


l     i     i     i     i     i     i     I     i 
Ctf"*"-  ^o>oo*>^»-* 

U-*    O^   *»  <"*•  N    (N 


c    i     i     t     i     <     i     i     i     i     :     t    c   i     i 

NirmcoONin-^-£o        c  CO 
rwno>niNNr'(nsc>e  cn 


\C  r   O    esJO-tfOXX    XOi/^r^O*'f,«>X's-'^sOX\OOi)^- 
Ni/>iAChNfMCCO*COCOxvC'7^lN'ffiO<-|(*,"i*,vCsyOCC 


rsi  \C   fM  fsj  — 


~h*  III 


f*»  0*«  v£-^  C*^  XOf"^flJ",J'  >y 

C   >A   in  N  N      -     ■(•)  in      »C   ift      *     >"£   r*  -^      - 
(M(sj,«Hrii—    CN^HNCCO-HM-CfM-NiTvO 


^  c^ 

C   QC 


I 


I        I        I 


I        I        I 


I        I       I        I        I 


C   C   *i  c 

CO    ITI    N    m 


<eC^^iAvC'~',JO,100>-TN'C 

ir*         —  —         x— 'CN-^-^CNCNjr-*   —   r-r 


h  C   h  ^  in 


x       —    r 


ai 


t     >r     r    ^ 


e 

eg 

u 

BG 

^ 

M| 

c 

_ 

X 

N 

c 

— 

< 

i 

n 

^ 

U 

-^ 

V 

— 

— 

X 

_ 

» 

L. 

5 

r 

r: 

n 

bo 

4J 

~ 

>. 

SI 

r 

■w 

B 

e 

^ 

CJ5 

X 

=: 

e 

b 

1 

u 

te 

— 

»t 

ea. 

cr 

k. 

^ 

ao 

T 

(T 

r- 

^ 

*T 

— 

— 

CI 

B; 

g 

j; 

— 

3 

Li 

Q 

cr 

EV 

B 

v. 

cr: 

,^ 

x 

J 

c 

fl? 

_ 

> 

T 

• 

H 

^ 

■- 

5 

L. 

cr 

* 

s 

K 

s 

^ 

E 

5 

CV 

md 

u 

c 

s 

k. 

™ 

l> 

X 

>■ 

c 

im 

C 

^- 

w 

D 

c 

— 

— 

-t 

u 

J! 

T 

— 

J* 

'=  § 


krSCfiHUSZEnZ.lbkiBKKGtS 


-  *t  i*  .:  ^  c  ~  r  ^  L"  *■  i*  -*  c  -  ^  r 

C     IT     ~     ~     T    -    (*!    N    l"    *    o    vj    ,"   n    -    -    - 

n  r«!  tv  m  ri  n  in  fj  "4  rsi  rs'  r*  p>]  rsi  —  r«  t— 


>r   ^^  J*  -^ 


c 


■5 

•c 
< 


Iftd 


| 

i 
c 


I      fc 


I     S 


li 

=  l 


-lr-# 


h*    X   C    C 


- 

!  U 

M> 

— 

«■ 

— 

— 

•v 

^H^ 

•*m^ 

— - 

L. 

» 

SIX 

-ri  x 

1 

V 

V 

su 

^_ 

X 

■oji- 

*J 

u 

y 

Cy 

~ 

ff 

<! 

— 

■M 

— • 

■J 

1  |  c 

V, 

u 

r  |  v. 

c 

c 

^ 

c 

a 

Cy 

^J 

XI 

cr 

« 

ee 

SB 

c 

r 

>•   • 

s 

5 

~ 

2 

» 

T. 

cr 

X 

*■.■ 

_— 

e 

>^-^ 

~ 

c 

e 

e 

- 

; 

*■ 

U  -X 

0) 

t 

c? 

c 

-25- 

percentage  of  value-added  originating  in  optimal  plants  in  1870,  shows 
that  this  is  not  necessarily  the  case;  a  combination  of  plants  that 
were  "too  small"  and  "too  large"  could  produce  a  total  value-added  and 
number  of  plants  consistent  with  an  optimal  range.   In  a  number  of 
other  industries  (malt  and  distilled  liquors,  cotton  and  wool  tex- 
tiles, clothing,  millinery,  wooden  furniture,  leather  tanning,  boots 
and  shoes,  farm  machinery  and  carriages  and  wagons)  the  number  of 
establishments  in  1870  was  greater  than  the  number  of  minimum  effi- 
cient scale  plants,  suggesting  that  relatively  few  establishments  in 
those  industries  had  achieved  an  efficient  scale  in  1870.   Except  for 
textiles,  these  industries  in  1870  were  still  dominated  by  small-scale 
artisan  shops.   Most  agricultural  implements  manufacturers,  for 
example,  were  little  more  than  village  blacksmiths  and  handmade  shoes 
still  had  not  been  displaced  by  the  mass  produced  factory  product. 

By  1900,  the  number  of  establishments  and  the  distribution  of  value- 
added  had  changed  so  that  only  in  millinery,  wooden  household  fur- 
niture, and  wagons  and  carriages  was  the  number  of  establishments  in 
an  industry  greater  than  the  predicted  range.   In  four  industries 
there  were  fewer  establishments  in  the  industry  than  predicted:   Three 
of  these  were  ones  in  which  there  had  been  rapid  technological  change; 
meat  packing,  tobacco,  and  blast  furnaces.   The  other  industry,  brick- 
making,  is  one  of  the  lowest  value-to-weight  products  and,  hence,  one 
on  which  cheaper  transportation  is  most  likely  to  have  the  greatest 
effect. 

The  nature,  timing  and  extent  of  technological  change  influences 
how  the  hypothetical  number  of  1870  optimal  plants  compared  with  the 


-26- 

number  of  plants  actually  in  an  industry  at  any  moment.   Consider  the 
case  of  meat  packing.   In  1870  and  1880,  the  number  of  plants  in  the 
industry  lay  within  the  range  of  the  numbers  of  optimal  1870  plants, 
but,  by  1390,  there  were  fewer  plants  in  the  industry  than  we  predict 
on  the  basis  of  no  changes  in  technology  or  externalities  from  1870. 
Yet  this  is  precisely  when  the  industry  was  revolutionized  by  the 
introduction  of  the  refrigerator  car  with  a  nationwide  distribution 
network  and  the  conversion  of  meat-packing  to  a  high  volume,  con- 
tinuous disassembly  process  making  full  use  of  by-products.   Firms 
such  as  Swift  and  Company,  P.  D.  Armour  and  the  Cudahy  Packing  Company 
drove  smaller  firms  out  of  business  as  they  integrated  vertically  and 
spread  out  horizontally  into  cities  other  than  Chicago  (Swift  and 
Armour)  or  Omaha  (Cudahy)  (Chandler,  1977,  pp.  300-301;  Yeager,  1981). 

A  similar  story  can  be  told  for  the  tobacco  industry  which  was 
revolutionized  by  Duke's  adoption  of  Bonsack's  continuous-process 
cigarette-making  machine  in  1885  and  his  national  advertising  campaign 
to  promote  the  product  (Chandler,  1977,  pp.  290-291;  Tennant,  1950). 
As  a  result,  in  1890,  the  number  of  tobacco  plants  was  closer  to  the 
lower-bound  number  of  optimally-sized  1870  plants  than  had  been  the 
case  in  1880.   By  1900,  with  the  American  Tobacco  Company  dominating 
the  industry  by  merger  and  predatory  practices,  the  industry  had  been 
transformed  to  one  with  fewer  plants  than  we  would  have  predicted  had 
those  changes  not  taken  place  since  1870. 

This  pattern  is  repeated  in  industry  after  industry  although  in 
some  industries,  such  as  agricultural  implements,  it  is  difficult  to 


-27- 

point  to  specific  innovations  other  than  the  adoption  of  factory  pro- 
duction, superior  machine  tools  and  more  reliable  supplies  of  low  cost 
metals  to  account  for  the  marked  change  in  the  number  and  size  of 
plants.   The  data  in  Table  5  reveal  the  magnitude  of  industry 


Table  5 


adjustment  towards  optimal  plant  sizes  by  1900.   They  do  not,  however, 
necessarily  measure  the  extent,  degree  and  significance  of  tech- 
nological progress.   Some  changes  came  about  because  of  widespread 
adoption  of  factory  production  to  take  advantage  of  improvements  in 
transportation  and  distribution  but  using  pre-Civil  War  technology. 
The  most  rapid  relative  adjustment  was  in  the  boot  and  shoe  industry 
in  which  the  artisan  producer  was  virtually  driven  out  of  business, 
except  in  the  repair  of  shoes,  in  favor  of  factory-made  products 
(Hazard,  1921;  Clark,  1929).   One  would  add  in  passing  that  the  switch 
to  mass-produced  shoes  was  accompanied  not  only  by  a  decline  in  price 
but  by  improvements  in  fit  and  durability  (Keir,  1920).   Leather 
tanning  also  underwent  a  marked  change  as  a  result  of  improvements  in 
the  chemical  industry  and  the  effects  of  concentration  in  the  meat- 
packing industry  which  confer  a  degree  of  monopoly  power  on  the 
packers.   In  the  brewing  industry,  brewmasters,  led  by  Pabst,  estab- 
lished vertically  integrated  plants  to  supply  far-flung  markets  via 
temperature-controlled  tank  cars.   The  clothing  industry,  revolu- 
tionized by  the   sewing  machine  and  the  adoption  of  standard  sizes, 
underwent  the  fourth  most  rapid  transition.   The  agricultural  machinery 
industry  which  experienced  the  fifth  most  dramatic  relative  change 


-28- 


u 

X 

re 

Id 

C 

li- 

re 

re 

e. 

a 

o 

re 

r-. 

>. 

u 

j-i 

CO 

re 

2 

S 

X 

— 

C 

IJ 

to 

m 

C 

^ 

e 

a 

0    1 

A 

e 

o 

— < 

fc-  r~ 

H 

0)  oc 

tt 

_:   — 

4J 

E 

- 

3 

(5 

Z 

I 

01 

z 

• 

-3     > 

a. 

H 

i    — 

F 

^ 

^     - 

•» 

<N 

O 

u^ 

fn  n  n 

CO 

o 

<    -C   in 

r*. 

C*   — 

rsi 

—     ON 

m 

«o  — <  — 

!      ^    « 

c    re 

01 

r 

CM] 

CM 

rvi 

-*    CM 

1              — < 

re  -1 

5 

SL     a, 

— 

~ 

K 

T5 

X 

<r 

r- 

l*~ 

CO   sC  N 

o 

ir> 

—  r»*  it* 

cc 

00  f^» 

•x- 

^-    ITS 

cc 

<T    CM    PM 

■ 
It    N    sD 

CT> 

c 

C 

O   M    ITi 

C   «T    l/">          1 

CM 

-     1 

&• 

r^ 

r^ 

c*  o  -a* 

C 

r-» 

00    <T    «» 

O" 

*r  r*. 

<r 

00   c 

C    00    CM 

t 

I 

1 

I 

ff< 

e 

"" 

—    P* 

1 
i 

i 

>c 

<• 

cc  — •  m 

c~ 

rsi 

r»*    «  CT» 

— )    U-i 

CM 

r*.   «j 

<r 

r«*  \r\  mt 

e  0*  r*       ! 

CO 

00 

-4 

pn 

»? 

cm  or*  cm 

C* 

—    c  m 

r-* 

r^  m 

CC 

00  — < 

CM 

N     K     -- 

C  ov  r>        j 

l"N 

CM   CM 

rg 

r~ 

— < 

i 

I, 

c> 

<t 

X> 

O 

cc 

C  m  *© 

-3- 

cc   f* 

<r 

CM   \C 

CC 

rt    N    N 

I 

r-  -  >e       j 

CO 

»— t 

r* 

U-l 

p- i  oo  ** 

c 

r-j 

C*    »»    m 

X 

O   «T 

o 

ir,  sc 

—i 

new 

r^  kA  »c 

r->  ■«< 

r-j 

■<r  c 

CN 

rsi 

CC   m 

1 

1-  — 

&>  E 

I  £ 

Z  " 


e 
u 


e:       u.   r 


KC  u 

C   —  C  >- 

— I  —         o 

-*  —  -z    - 

re  r  re  —  —   c 


re    x    I  .= 


•c       —   o    o   c 


recu—  cn-ai-icc- 
ci  -*  u  re  —  cooai  — 
ZBtilSSQHUSSS 


C    CC    CC   —   ^Jrvj'^r*^^' 


C    —    1*1    C    "-1" 
f*>  —   —  —   rsi 


P4inir 


(^     (•%     f•^     (»\     (•^^ 


- 

_ 

0.1 

K 

— 

&£ 

s 

<► 

_ 

" 

— 

^ 

T 

(t 

w 

— 

i- 

— 

c 

■J 

L) 

«; 

— 

ei 

•z 

z 

^ 

r; 

Z 

= 

■— 

S 

h 

tn 

Id 

L. 

^ 

(0 

— 

.£ 

_ 

— 

be 

» 

r. 

u 

~ 

'- 

>- 

« 

^ 

— 

pH 

B 

V 

3 

= 

G 

^ 

t- 

H 

—H 

^ 

— 

c 

u. 

~ 

ir 

- 

(C 

— 

* 

3 

C 

^- 

-7 

u 

Q 

Zl 

a> 

u 

EJ 

^ 

a. 

CT 

cr. 

c: 

LC 

L- 

— 

z 

c 

0 

(B 

^ 

T 

X 

Li 

T 

• 

H 

T" 

TT 

z 

u 

H 

^ 

e 

<u 

u- 

— 

i." 

CT 

>. 

r. 

e 

C 

1 

B 

■_ 

— 

r 

c 

k. 

3 

Li 

e 

c 

w 

~ 

LiJ 

rj 

~ 

— 

f 

— 

li 

V 

Li 

p— 

.'. 

3) 

V 

-* 

r 

.■-; 

E 

= 

— 

•n 

B 

— 

U 

— 

y 

^ 

o 

c 

F 

2 

™ 

■> 

— 

C 

— 

c; 

- 

TT 

v 

cc 

t? 

w 

0) 

L 

W 

EL 

y 

l 

fl 

(T 

L- 

« 

CO 

E 

Sfl 

= 

^ 

0. 

= 

C/j 

X 

3_ 

- 

-J? 

« 

a_ 

2 

0 

-29- 


finally  broke  with  its  blacksraithing  origins  to  become  a  mass-produced, 
factory  product.   At  the  opposite  end  of  the  scale,  industries  such  as 
brick  making,  sheet  metal  and  printing  underwent  remarkably  little 
change  by  way  of  transforming  the  industry.   Nor  is  there  evidence  of 
revolutionary  change  in  the  flour  milling  industry;  despite  the  adop- 
tion of  reduction  milling  and  the  development  of  national  brands  such 
as  Pillsbury  and  Gold  Medal,  the  small  flour  mill  continued  in 
existence.   Other  "laggard"  industries  such  as  wagons  and  carriages  or 
saddlery  and  harness,  are  less  surprising  as  these  underwent  no  tech- 
nological change  nor  probably  did  they  benefit  from  the  development  of 
a  national  market. 

Conclusion 

In  aggregate  terms,  few  industries  showed  a  dramatically  different 
structure  in  1900  than  had  been  present  in  1870.   Some  of  the  most 
pronounced  changes  were  in  those  industries  which  had  successfully 
moved  from  the  workshop  or  small  factory  serving  local  needs  to  fac- 
tories serving  a  wider  clientele;  industries  such  as  boots  and  shoes, 
leather  tanning,  brewing,  clothing  and  agricultural  implements.   With 
few  exceptions,  these  were  not  the  industries  undergoing  rapid  tech- 
nological change  after  the  Civil  War.    For  the  most  part  they  were 
taking  advantage  of  pre-Civil  War  technology  and  the  post-War  revolu- 
tion in  transportation  and  distribution.   The  typical  plant  in  these 
industries  in  1900  was  no  larger  than  an  efficient  plant  in  1870  would 
have  been. 


-30- 

In  some  industries,  however,  the  average  scale  of  operation  by 
1900  was  much  larger  than  that  of  an  efficient  plant  of  1870.   These 
were  generally  industries  which  had  experienced  technological  change 
permitting  high-speed,  continuous-production  processes  and  had  also 
taken  advantage  of  mass  marketing  and  distribution  for  their  product. 
However,  only  a  few  establishments  in  each  industry  took  advantage  of 
these  opportunities.   Their  output  level  was  often  many  times  greater 
than  that  of  even  the  largest  1870  efficient  plants  and,  for  the  most 
part,  they  survived.   The  rest  of  the  plants  in  these  industries 
remained  small.   They  were  the  typical  producing  units  but  they  are 
generally  ignored.   Certainly,  they  do  not  appear  in  Chandler's  model, 
Bigness  is  better  documented;  more  heroic  and  although  big  firms  made 
their  mark,  the  successful  coexistence  of  small  producers  is  at  least 
as  deserving  of  study.   Their  survival  seems  to  stem  from  the  rapid 
exhaustion  of  production  economies  in  many  activities  and  the  ability 
of  the  small  firm  to  carve  out  a  niche  catering  to  local  tastes  and 
needs  not  met  by  a  mass-marketed,  homogenized  product. 


-31- 


Footnotes 

*I  wish  to  thank  Fred  Bateraan  and  Larry  Neal  for  their  helpful 
comments  and  suggestions  on  this  version  of  the  paper.   Earlier  work 
from  which  this  paper  was  derived  benefitted  from  the  advice  and  com- 
ments of  Richard  Arnould,  Barry  Baysinger,  Jan  Brueckner,  Larry 
Davidson,  Wayne  Lee,  Julian  Simon  and  George  Stigler. 

The  difficulties  of  raising  impersonal  capital  were  a  frequent 
lament  of  nineteenth  century  industrialists,  particularly  in  the  South 
and  West.  The  issues  are  discussed  in  Livermore  (1935).  Various  stu- 
dies have  been  made  of  the  progress  of  limited  liability  and  the 
granting  of  corporate  charters  to  business.  None,  however,  is  compre- 
hensive. See,  for  example,  Evans  (1948),  Kuehnl  (1959),  Wilson  (1964) 
and  Wolfe  (1965). 

2 

Daniel  Pratt,  for  example,  raised  the  $110,000  for  his  Prattville 

Manufacturing  Company  No.  1  from  personal  resources,  friends  and  rela- 
tives (Miller,  1972,  p.  17).   The  large  New  England  textile  mills 
were,  however,  able  to  attract  institutional  funds  for  operating  capi- 
tal and  expansion,  and  sell  equity  to  finance  the  initial  construction 
(Davis,  1957;  Davis,  1958;  Davis,  1960). 

3 
Even  in  cities  such  as  Lowell  or  Lawrence  centered  upon  large 

developed  water  rights,  future  expansion  could  only  be  met  by  improve- 
ments in  the  use  of  the  available  water  or  the  adoption  of  supplemen- 
tary steam  power  (Atack,  Bateman  and  Weiss,  1980).   Pressure  upon 
existing  water  rights  led  to  the  pioneering  research  and  development 


-32- 

work  of  Che  Locks  and  Canal  Company  at  Lowell  and  its  chief  engineer, 
James  B.  Francis,  inventor  of  the  Francis  turbine  (Francis,  1868). 

4 
For  an  attempt  at  measuring  the  geographic  spread  of  steam  power 

as  coal  became  available,  see  Atack  and  Bateman  (1983). 

See,  for  example,  Atack  (1976;  1977)  and  Sokoloff  (1981)  for  the 
antebellum  period  and  Ringstad  (1974)  for  comparable  results  for 
modern  industry. 

See,  for  example,  Nerlove  (1963);  Soskice  (1968);  Zellner  and 
Revankar  (1969);  Ringstad  (1974);  Christensen,  Jorgensen  and  Lau 
(1973);  Christensen  and  Greene  (1976). 

The  logarithm  of  the  likelihood  function  corresponding  to 
equation  [1]  is: 

ln£  =  constant  -  -y  In  a     +  In  J(X;V) 

"  n  K  ~r 

Z      In  (V  ).  -  InA  -  u  ■  InL.  -  0  •  ln(-^-) 

m  X  X  Ll, 

1=1  i 


2a2 


2 
where  a  is  the  variance  of  the  normally  and  independently  distributed 

random  error  term  with  mean  zero,  n  is  the  number  of  observations  and 

J(A;V)  is  the  Jacobian  of  the  monotonic  transformation. 

J(X;V)  =  Eln(l+9V.).   Ordinary  least  squares  minimizes  the  last  term 

i       1 
of  equation  [2]  for  any  predetermined  value  of  0,  yielding  a 

conditional  maximum  for  the  likelihood  function.   By  varying  0  and 

evaluating  (InA  -  constant)  the  estimate  of  0,(0),  follows  a  chi-square 

distribution  such  that: 


[2: 


-33- 


in£(e)  -  lni(e)   <  1/2  x2(n) 

max 

where  n  is  the  confidence  interval.   Using  n  =  .05  yields  a  value  for 

2 
1/2  Y  of  1.94.   Thus  ln£(e)    <  1.94  in  the  test  for  the  confidence 
A  max 

interval  around  the  value  of  0,  the  global  maximum  likelihood 
function  can  be  determined. 

8 
The  data  are  from  the  samples  drawn  from  the  manufacturing  census 

of  1350,  1860  and  1870  by  Fred  Bateraan  and  Tom  Weiss.   Sokoloff  (1981) 
also  reports  relatively  slight  support  favoring  a  variable  scale 
elasticity  production  function  in  1820  and  1850  data.   Similar  fin- 
dings of  increasing  scale  elasticity  with  plant  size  have  been  noted 
by  Sokoloff  (private  communication)  and  James  (1982). 

9 
For  analogous  results  for  the  pre-Civil  War  period,  see  Atack 

(1977). 

10 

Manuscript  census  data.   The  higher  value-added  produced  in 

steam- powered  factories  as  compared  with  that  produced  in  water-driven 

plants  holds  across  virtually  every  industry,  in  each  region  and  in 

each  of  the  three  years  exasrained:   1350,  1860  and  1870.   It  is  also 

greater  than  can  be  accounted  for  by  the  elimination  of  seasonality. 

Steam-driven  factories  were  larger  and  the  machinery  was  probably 

driven  longer  and  harder  than  that  in  water-powered  plants. 

Similarly  a  technological  change  which  reduces  raw  material 
waste  would  increase  value-added  for  the  same  level  of  output. 


-34- 

Evidence  favoring  substantial  biased  technological  change  over  the 
period  1850-1919  is  given  in  Cain  and  Paterson  (1981)  and  in  James 
(1982)  for  the  period  1850-1900.   The  bias  was  generally  in  favor  of 
labor-saving  technological  change,  and  although  it  was  not  necessarily 
capital-using,  there  is  evidence  of  material-using  and  capital-using 
biases.   James'  (1982)  work  suggests  much  of  the  biased  technological 
change  occurs  from  1880  onward,  except  in  iron,  leather  tanning  and 
cotton  textiles.   However,  10  of  the  industries  in  this  study  (bread 
and  other  baked  goods;  malt  liquors;  tobacco;  millinery;  millwork; 
household  furniture;  saddlery  and  harness;  sheet  metal  work;  farm 
machinery;  and  transportation  equipment)  are  not  included  in  James' 
work. 

12 

The  theory  gives  no  guidance  over  the  appropriate  size  cate- 
gories, probably  because  modern  studies  applying  the  survivor  tech- 
nique have  to  rely  upon  census  size  classifications.   I  elected  to  use 
a  logarithmic  progression  of  size  categories;  the  limits  of  each  cate- 
gory are  double  those  of  the  next  smaller  category.   Because  of  the 
large  numbers  of  small  firms  in  many  industries  I  selected  $0-249 
value-added  (1860  dollars)  as  the  smallest  category.   The  largest  size 
groups  is  $250,000  or  more  value-added  (1860  dollars)  and  is  open- 
ended.   An  upper  bound  on  plant  value-added  for  plants  falling  in  this 
group  is  not  specified.   No  size  distribution  of  firms/plants  was 
published  before  1900  (U.S.  Census  Office,  1902). 

13 

James  (1982)  also  notes  the  generally  small  scale  of  optimal 

size  plants  though  his  results  suggest  some  significant  increases  in 

size  between  1860  and  1870. 


-35- 

14 

Only  one  integrated  blast-furnace  and  Bessemer  plant  was  in  the 

sample  and  its  inclusion  in  the  $128,000-255,990  category  resulted  in 
that  size  class  surviving.   On  the  other  hand,  there  were  only  three 
Bessemer  plants  in  operation  in  1370  (Jeans,  1880).   Nevertheless, 
there  was  a  marked  shift  in  favor  of  larger  blast  furnaces  to  econo- 
mize on  fuel  and  recycle  heat  otherwise  lost  in  the  process.   See  also 
Allen  (1967). 

In  these  industries  the  only  technical  changes  of  consequence  in 
the  production  process  were  the  McKay  welting  machine  in  boot  and  shoe 
manufacture  and  the  pneumatic  malting  process  in  brewing  (Hazard, 
1921;  Chandler,  1977). 


-36- 

3ibliography 

Abbott,  Edith  (1908/9),  "History  of  the  Employment  of  Women  in  the 
American  Cotton  Mill,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  16  No.  10 
(December  1908)  pp.  680-92  and  17  No.  1  (January  1909),  pp.  19-35. 

Allen,  Robert  C.  (1977),  "The  Peculiar  Productivity  History  of 

American  Blast  Furnaces,  1840-1913,"  Journal  of  Economic  History, 
37,  No.  3  (September),  605-33. 

Atack,  Jeremy  (1976),  "Estimation  of  Economies  of  Scale  in  Nineteenth 
Century  United  States  Manufacturing  and  the  Form  of  the  Production 
Function,"  Unpublished  Ph.D.  thesis,  Indiana  University. 

4tack,  Jeremy  (1977),  "Returns  to  Scale  in  Antebellum  United  States 
Manufacturing,"  Explorations  in  Economic  History,  14  No.  3 
(October)  337-359. 

Atack,  Jeremy  and  Bateman,  Fred  (1983),  "The  Development  of  Industrial 
Steam  Power  in  the  Midwest  with  Special  Reference  to  Indiana,"  The 
Old  Northwest  (forthcoming). 

Atack,  Jeremy;  Bateman,  Fred  and  Weiss,  Thomas  (1980),  "The  Regional 
Diffusion  and  Adoption  of  the  Steam  Engine  in  American 
Manufacturing,"  Journal  of  Economic  History,  40  No .  2  (June), 
281-308. 

Atack,  Jeremy;  3ateman,  Fred  and  Weiss,  Thomas  (1982),  "Risk,  the  Rate 
of  Return  and  the  Pattern  of  Investment  in  Nineteenth  Century 


-37- 

American  Manufacturing,"  Southern  Economic  Journal  49,  No.  1 
(July),  pp.  150-163. 

Bateman,  Fred  and  Weiss,  Thomas  (1975),  "Comparative  Regional 

Development  in  Antebellum  Manufacturing,"  Journal  of  Economic 
History,  35  No.  1  (March),  pp.  182-208. 

Bateman,  Fred  and  Weiss,  Thomas  (1981),  A  Deplorable  Scarcity:  The 
Failure  of  Industrialization  in  the  Slave  Economy,  Chapel  Hill: 
University  of  North  Carolina  Press. 

Box,  G.  E.  P.  and  Cox,  D.  R.  (1963),  "An  Analysis  of  Transformations," 
Journal  of  the  Royal  Statistical  Society,  Series  B,  26,  211-252. 

Bradford,  S.  S.  (1959),  "The  Negro  Ironworkers  in  Antebellum 

Virginia,"  Journal  of  Southern  History,  25,  No.  2  (May)  194-206. 

Cain,  Louis  P.  and  Paterson,  Donald  G.  (1981),  "Factor  Biases  and 
Technical  Change  in  Manufacturing:   The  American  System, 
1850-1919,"  Journal  of  Economic  History,  41  No.  2  (June),  341-360. 

Chandler,  Alfred  D.  (1977),  The  Visible  Hand:   The  Managerial 
Revolution  in  American  Business,  Cambridge,  Mass.:   Harvard 
University  Press. 

Christensen,  L.;  Jorgenson,  D.  and  Lau,  L.  (1973),  "Transcendental 
Logarithmic  Production  Functions,"  Review  of  Economics  and 
Statistics,  55  No.  1  (February)  28-45. 


-38- 

Christensen,  L.  R.  and  Green,  W.  H.  (1976),  "'Economies  of  Scale  in 

U.S.  Electric  Power  Generation,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  84 
No.  4  (August),  655-676. 

Clark,  Victor  (1929),  History  of  Manufactures  in  the  United  States, 
New  York:   McGraw-Hill  Co.,  Volume  II. 

Danhof,  Clarence  (1941),  "Farm-Making  Costs  and  the  'Safety  Valve'" 
1850-1860,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  49,  No.  3  (June), 
317-59. 

Davis,  Lance  E.  (1957),  "Sources  of  Industrial  Finance:   The  American 
Textile  Industry,  A  Case  Study,"  Explorations  in  Entrepreneurial 
History,  9  No .  2  (April)  190-203. 

Davis,  Lance  E.  (1958),  "Stock  Ownership  in  the  Early  New  England 

Textile  Industry,"  The  Business  History  Review,  32,  No.  2  (Summer) 
204-222. 

Davis,  Lance  E.  (1960),  "The  New  England  Textile  Mills  and  the  Capital 
Markets:   A  Study  of  Industrial  Borrowing,  1840-1860,"  Journal  of 
Economic  History,  20,  No.  1  (March),  1-30. 

Evans,  George  H.  (1948),  Business  Incorporations  in  the  United  States, 
1800-1943 ,  Baltimore:   Waverly  Press  for  the  National  Bureau  of 
Economic  Research. 

Francis,  James  B.  (1868),  Lowell  Hydraulic  Experiments,  New  York: 
D.  Van  Nostrand. 


-39- 

Hazard,  Blanche  E.  (1921),  The  Organization  of  the  Boot  and  Shoe 

Industry  in  Massachusetts  Before  1375,  Cambridge,  Mass.:   Harvard 
University  Press. 

Keir,  Malcolm  (1920),  Manufacturing  Industries  in  America,  New  York: 
The  Ronald  Press. 

Kuehnl,  George  J.  (1959),  The  Wisconsin  Business  Corporation,  Madison: 
University  of  Wisconsin  Press. 

James,  John  (1982),  "Structural  Change  in  American  Manufacturing, 

1850-190,"  unpublished  manuscript,  University  of  Virginia  (mimeo). 

Jeans,  J.  S.  (1880),  Steel:   Its  History,  Manufacture,  Properties  and 
Uses ,  London:   Spon. 

Livermore,  Shaw  (1935),  "Unlimited  Liability  in  Early  American 
Corporations,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  43,  No.  5 
(September),  674-687. 

Miller,  Randall  (1972),  "Daniel  Pratt's  Industrial  Urbanisra:   The 
Cottom  Mill  Town  in  Ante-Bellum  Alabama,"  Alabama  Historical 
Quarterly,  34  No.  1  (Spring),  pp.  5-35. 

Mitchell,  Broadus  (1928),  William  Gregg,  Factory  Master  of  the  Old 
South,  Chapel  Hill:   Univeristy  of  North  Carolina  Press. 

Montgomery,  James  (1840),  The  Cotton  Manufacture  of  the  United  States 
Contrasted  and  Compared  with  that  of  Great  Britain,  Glasgow:   John 

Niven. 


-40- 

Nerlove,  M.  (1963),  "Returns  Co  Scale  in  Electricity  Supply,"  in  C.  F. 
Christ  (ed.),  Measurement  in  Economics,  Stanford:   Stanford 
University  Press. 

Poor,  Henry  V.  (1890),  Manual  of  the  Railroads  of  the  United  States, 
New  York:   Poor. 

Reynolds,  A.  R.  (1957),  The  Daniel  Shaw  Lumber  Company,  New  York:   New 
York  University  Press. 

Ringstad,  V.  (1974),  "Some  Empirical  Evidence  on  Decreasing  Scale 
Elasticity,"  Econometrica,  42  No.  1  (January),  87-102. 

Saving,  T.  R.  (1961),  "Estimation  of  Optimum  Plant  Size  by  the 
Survivor  Technique,"  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  75,  4, 
569-607. 

Shepherd,  William  A.  (1967),  "What  Does  the  Survivor  Technique  Show 
About  Economies  of  Scale,"  Southern  Economics  Journal,  34,  No.  1, 
(January)  113-122. 

Sokoloff,  Kenneth  L.  (1981),  "Was  the  Transition  from  the  Artisanal 
Step  to  the  Small  Factory  Associated  with  Gains  in  Efficiency?: 
Evidence  from  the  U.S.  Manufacturing  Censuses  of  1820  and  1850," 
unpublished  manuscript,  University  of  California,  Los  Angeles 
(mimeo) . 

Soskice,  David  (1968),  "A  Modification  of  the  CES  Production  Function 
to  Allow  for  Changing  Returns  to  Scale  over  the  Function,"  Review 
of  Economics  and  Statistics,  50,  No.  4  (November),  446-448. 


-41- 

Stigler,  George  J.  (1958),  "The  Economies  of  Sale,"  Journal  of  Law  and 
Economics ,  1,  3,  54-71. 

Tennant,  Richard  B.  (19  50),  The  American  Cigarette  Industry,  New 
Haven:   Yale  University  Press. 

U.S.  Census  Office  (1873,  1883,  1893,  1902).   Ninth-Twelfth  Census, 
Washington,  D.C.:   Government  Printing  Office. 

U.S.  Bureau  of  the  Census  (1975),  Historical  Statistics  of  the  United 
States,  Colonial  Times  to  1970,  Washington,  D.C.:   Government 
Printing  Office. 

Ware,  Caroline  (1931),  The  Early  New  England  Cotton  Manufacture,  New 
York:   Houghton  Mifflin  Co. 

Weiss,  Leonard  W.  (1964),  "The  Survival  Technique  and  the  Extent  of 
Suboptimal  Capacity,"  The  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  72,  2, 
246-261. 

Williamson,  Jeffrey  and  Swanson,  Joseph  A.  (1966),  "The  Growth  of 
Cities  in  the  American  Northeast,  1820-1870,"  Explorations  in 
Economic  History,  4,  No.  1  Supplement,  pp.  1-101. 

Wilson,  Livy  T.  (1964),  "Florida  Business  Corporatons  1838-1885," 
unpublished  Ph.D.  thesis,  University  of  Illinois. 

Wolfe,  Arthur  D.  (1965),  "Ohio  Business  Incorporations,  1803-1851," 
unpublished  M.A.  thesis,  University  of  Illinois. 


-42- 

Yeager,  Mary  (1981),  Competition  and  Regulation:   The  Development  of 
Oligopoly  in  the  Meat  Packing  Industry,  Greenwich,  Conn.:   JAI 
Press. 

Zellner,  Arnold  and  Revankar,  N.  S.  (1969),  "Generalized  Production 
Functions,"  Review  of  Economic  Studies,  36  No.  2  (April)  241-250. 


D/108A 


HECKMAN 

BINDERY  INC. 


JUN95 


,   J>N.  MANCHESTER,  | 

lBounJ-T°'Plca5t     ,h